■^TiUDNVSOl^ i ^lOSANCFief;^ %83AINI13WV ^lUBRARY-Qr^ ^OJUVDJO"^ ,^MEUNIVER% ^lOSANCflfj> ^OFCAIIFO;?^ ^HIBRARYOc. ^llIBRARYQr^ ^tfOJiivjjo't^ ^«!fojnvjjo>^ O li. ANCnfj> 9^ v>> ^ ,^;OFCAIIFO%, ^OFCAl!F0% "^^(^AHvaair^ ^^c/AHVHan-^' .\'rtEUNIVER5/'A < CO -< ■^Aa3AlNfl-3l\V^ ^OFCAllFOMj^ >&AHvaani^ ^■smmm^ "^/jaaAiNdJWV^ .^M^UNIv^?s•/A o _^lOSANCnfj> ^MlBRAffVQr^ ^l-lIBRAirY6>/^ '^/ia3AINrt-3WV ^\\^El!NIVERJ'/^ >- o ^lOSANCflfx* o ^^rnhrn^^ ^OFCAIIFO;?^ ^OFCAIIFO/?^ >&AHv«ani>J'^ "^^AiivHan^ o^illBRARrO/ <>^IUBRARY6// ^OdllVJ-jO"^ ^OJIIVO-JO-'^'' < ^TilJONVSOl^ v^lOSANCnCT/ o -< ^^,OFCAIIFO%, ^.OFCAIIFOMfe, s = ^^'rtFUNIVERJ/^ v^lOSANCnfj> (^ .^m^ -it. O ":V89AINfl]WV' A>^lUBRARYQc. 5 i 1^ ^ &AJivHan-^^ .a^llRftAPV/O* .^xf.llRftAPV/l* <«flIMrVFPC/K .irKAMTIFIFr. Offr> ^ U A. CO. L. i •N THE LAW RELATING TO TRADE UNIONS. T H E L A \V KEI.ATING TO TRADE UNIONS SIR WILLIAM ERLE, FtHOlERLV CHIEF JUSTICE IN THK COMMON PLEAS. ITDnbon : MAC-MILLAN AND CO. 1S69. LONDON : R. CLAY, SONS, AND TAYLOR, PRINTERS, BREAD STRKKT HII L. . T CONTENTS. FAGE INTRODUCTION vii .CHAPTER I. COMMON LAW RELATING TO TRADE UNIONS. Section i. Formation and Force of Unions i „ 2. Right to Free Course for Trade in General . . 5 „ 3- Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour (that is, to freedom to dispose of labour and capital according to the will of the owner) .... 11 „ 4. Proceedings for Violation of the Right to Free- dom for the Course of Trade 28 (a) Action for Civil Wrongs. (d) Indictment for Criminal Wrongs other than Conspiracy. (<:) Indictment for Conspiracy. 5. Statutable and Professional Restraints of Free- dom to Labour 42 (a) Restraints by Law, as by Factory Acts. (1^) Professional Fees. 6. The Roots and Crowtli of the Connnon Law . 47 729620 CONTENTS. CHAPTER II. STATl'TE LAW RELATING TO TRADE UNIUNS. Section i. Statutes prior to 6 George IV. c. 129 .... 55 „ 2. The Statute 6 George IV. c. 129 56 (os/}, have aid from the 44th section of the friendly Societies' Act, 18 and 19 Vict. c. 63. Chai'. I. Comir.oii Law. § I. Forma- tion mid Force of Unions. §2. Right to Free Course for Trade in General. 772^^ LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common Law. \ 2. Right to Free Course for Trade in General. and applies to a multitude of relations between man and man, relations which vary in countless permutation by the addition or subtraction of a circumstance ; and the unlawfulness depends on the degree of restraint resulting from the circumstances. Questions of degree cannot be defined without a standard of measure : unlaw^- ful restraint of trade, therefore, cannot be de- fined, but it may be described ; and the best description I can offer is this, that at common law every person has individually, and the public also have collectively, a right to require that the course of trade should be kept free from unreasonable obstruction. Neither a grant of this right, nor a pro- hibition of the violation thereof, is found in the direct terms of a law ; but proceedings for the violation of the right are recorded, and in these proceedings the grant of the right, and the prohibition of the violation thereof, are assumed to exist. The right to security for person and property is not granted affirma- tively, but assaults and thefts are frequently subjects of recorded legal proceedings in which i this right is assumed. The law has been de- scribed as jiibciis Jioncsta, proJiibeiis contraj'ia : I this may be true of written law, but in un- ! written law the Jussam is to be found in suits I for violating \\\q proJiibitiim. TO TRADE UNIONS. Many examples might be given of other rights to a free course in other matters which are known to the law not by express grant, but by enforcement of prohibition against violation thereof. The common law rights to a free course for passage on highways, or for light to the eyes, or for air to the lungs, or for the flow of the stream of water to the land of riparian pro- prietors, are not created by express grant, nor are they more capable of being perceived by any direct sense than the right to a free course for trade, there being no property either in any particle of light, or in air, or in running water, or in any passage on ways ; but the existence of each of these rights is made known by actions or indictments for the infringement thereof It may be worth adding, that the right to a free course for air or water is a right to quality as well as quantity. If either air or water is fouled in an unreasonable degree, action lies for a wrong in the class of nuisances ; and the degree which is unreasonable is constantly shifting according as density of neighbourhood increases. These are examples of the application of the law re- lating to other nuisances, besides those relating to the free course for trade, in respect of air or water, light or passage, above referred to. The right to a free course for trade is of great importance to commerce and productive CiiAr. i. Commcn § 2. Right io Free Course for Trade in Ce'iernl. THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I Common Law. § 2. Right fo Free Course for Traiie .« Geiteral. industry, and has been carefully maintained b}- those who have administered the common law during the time to which our records extend. The judgment of Parker, C.J., in Mitchel v. Reynolds (i P. Williams, i8i), is an authority showing the principle, and a limitation of it. The question was, whether a contract operating as a partial restraint of the trade of the vendor of the good-will of certain premises was valid ; and the answer was in the affirmative, provided the restraint was not unreasonable with regard to the public interest, and not greater than was required for the interest of the purchaser (the party restraining), and provided also that the party restrained (the vendor) received value for that which he gave up. In that judgment pre- vious cases showing restraint of trade to be illegal are examined, and the reasons for estab- lishing the exceptive limitation are shown to be founded on the interests of truth and ex- pediency. The report of this case in SmitJis Leading Cases (vol. i. p. 356, 6th ed.), collects the principles of numerous decisions following Mit- chel V. Reynolds, and defining more exactly the exceptive limitation. The laws relating to fairs, markets, and staples ; the prohibitions against forestalling, engrossing, regrating, monopolies, and all similar contrivances for affecting prices otherwise than by TO TRADE UNIONS. competition, have their origin in a purpose of keeping the course of trade free from obstruc- tion, and enabling buyers and sellers to deal on the terms which free competition determines. These rules were made for the purpose of securing supply in times when stores were small, and transit difficult, and famine near if supply was delayed. Now, their utility, and therewith their operation, has nearly ceased under altered circumstances from the advance of civilization, it being found that supply is best secured by leaving mercantile speculation free. Accordingly, it was ruled by Lord Ellenborough in R. v. Cleasby (about the year 1812), that the engros- sing of all the oil of a whaling season was no offence at common law in the then state of society; and he so held notwithstanding the case of R. v. Waddington, quoted below. The Legislature, by the 12 Geo. IIL c. 71, repealed the statutes declaratory of the common law against engrossing ; and the 7 & 8 Vict. c. 24, s. i, enacts that no suit, civil or criminal, shall lie for engrossing. At the same time, by s. 4, the common law protection of the free course for trade against obstruction by means of falsehood is expressly continued. (See Russell on Crimes, by Greaves, b. ii., c. 19, vol. i., p. 252, 4th ed.) A free course for trade has been carefully maintained from the earliest times. Lord Coke Chai'. I. Common Law. § 2. Right to Free Course for Trade in General. lO THE LAW RELATING Chap. I. Common Law. § 2. Right to Free Course for Trade in (General. ha.s collected some early authorities in his TJiird Institute, c. 89, on Forestalling. He goes back to the time of Ethelstan, and refers to laws in the time of that king, and also to laws in the time of the Conqueror, making provision for buying and selling in open market, by for- bidding traffic above a certain value outside of a town unless with a witness. The clause in Magna Charta securing to each person his liber- ties is construed by him to include the right to a free course for trade possessed by the subjects of England {Second Institute, p. 47). There is also a conviction reported by him in the 43d Assize of Edward III., for affecting the market price of an article by spreading a false report. To the authority of Lord Coke I would add a reference to the reports of some cases ; and among them to Davenant v. Hurdis, in the time of Elizabeth (Moore, 576), deciding that a bye-law of the Merchant Taylors' Company, restricting the dressing of cloths to the freemen of the Company, was void for monopoly ; and to the City of London's case (8 Co. 121 b), deciding that a charter from the King, granting that none but those free of the City should trade therein, was void for the same reason ; also to the case of Monopolies (11 Co. 87^), where Lord Coke refers to a very ancient law, " You shall not take in pledge the nether and upper TO TRADE UNIONS. millstone, quia aniinam siiani apposnit tibi" (Deut. xxiv. 6) and says that by this it appears that every man's trade maintains his life, and that therefore he ought not to be deprived nor dispossessed of it any more than of his life. I would also refer to R. •z^. Waddington (i East, 143), in the time of George III., where the defendant was convicted and punished for engrossing hops — that is, buying them wholesale with intent to sell them again wholesale. The arguments that were used by counsel and adopted by the Court in these cases, in support of the right to a free course for trade, show that the governing intention of those who administered the law was to promote the good of the community according to the light of their time, without partiality for any class, unless more scrupulous care for the protection of the less rich against the more rich class can be considered partiality. The intention of the judges in Waddington's case was in this sense entirely beneficent, al- though the prohibition there enforced against buying wholesale with intent to sell again whole- sale has been since found under altered cir- cumstances to be a mistake, as ^bove explained. III. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. — Under the general principle, operating upon all trade, which has been considered above, the Chap. I. Common Law. § 2. Right to Free Course for Trade in General. §3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. THE LAW RELATING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. law relating to freedom in disposing of either labour or capit?!, or both, is included. Every person has a right under the laiv, as betzveen him and his fellow subjects, to full freedom in dis- posing of his ozvn labour or his ozvn capital according to his ozvn will. It follows that every other person is subject to the correlative duty arising therefrom, and is prohibited from any obstruction to the fullest exercise of this right which can be made compatible zvith the exercise of similar rights by others. Every act causing an obstruction to another in the exercise of the right comprised within this description — done, not in the exercise of the actor's own right, but for the purpose of obstruc- tion — would, if damage should be caused thereby to the party obstructed, be a violation of this prohibition ; and the violation of this prohibition by a single person is a wrong, to be remedied either by action or by indictment, as the case may be. It is equally a wrong whether it be done by one or by many — subject to this observ^ation, that a combination of many to do a wrong, in a matter where the public has an interest, is a substantive offence of conspiracy. It is equally a wrong, whether the obstruction be by means of an act unlawful in itself, on the part of the party obstructing, or by means of an act not otherwise unlawful. TO TRADE UNIONS. 13 Whether an act which does obstruct is un- lawful seems to me to depend, under some circumstances, on the purpose of the actor : an example will help to explain my meaning. In R. V. Rowlands (5 Cox C. C. 436) ^ some of the defendants gave refreshment, or money, or advice to workmen going to the factory of Messrs. Perry, and thereby induced them to go away. The gift in each case might be for a purpose of beneficence towards the receiver, and might be lawful. But if it appeared that the refresh- ment produced incapacity, and the money paid the railway fare of a stupified man to an unknown place of concealment, and the persua- sion deluded him into a railway carriage to be carried to that place, where he was to be abandoned, and if it further appeared that their absence brought ruin on Messrs. Perry, the jus- tification on the ground of beneficent intention would be rebutted, and an act of obstruction done for the purpose of causing unjustified damage would remain proved, and would, in my opinion, be an act of unlawful obstruction which would render the parties to it liable to action or to indictment, as the case might be. These propositions assume that a person has a right to do as he chooses with his own, whe- ther labour or capital, within the limits set by ^ See Appendix A, p. 8i. Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. 14 THE LAW RELATING Chai'. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Cours" for Trade in Labour. Rules relat- ing to nui- sance. law ; that a right involves a prohibition against the infringement thereof; and that a prohibition involves a remedy for the violation thereof If these propositions are sound, they may serve the purpose of giving a general notion of the direc- tion of the law, and may be useful in suggesting the limits to which relaxation of restraint of trade ought to be carried. For effecting this purpose very wide propositions are pertinent. At the same time I am aware that such proposi- tions assist but slightly in deciding specific cases of nuisance by obstruction, each of which in- volves for the most part many questions, of which I subjoin a few examples. In the first place, it is a general rule relating to all nuisances, whether by obstruction or otherwise, that unlawfulness begins at a certain degree of annoyance, and that this degree is to be measured not by an exact standard, but on a supposed estimate of what is reasonable by men assumed to be prudent. In these words the defective nomenclature for legal ideas is ex- emplified, seeing that the terms "nuisance," "obstruction," "annoyance," may or may not denote unlawfulness. Secondly, the lawful exer- cise of a right is not a wrong. Where there are conflicting interests, the limits for the exer- cise of the rights relating to such interests vary as circumstances vary, and the adjustment of TO TRADE UNIONS. 15 the line where lawfuhiess ends and excess begins is not easy, because it is perpetually shifting. Each competitor in trade may hinder another, but the hindrance may not amount to unlawful obstruction. The process of adjustment of the line of lawfulness between rights which appear to conflict — the line where the exercise of a right is brought by excess to the confine of a wrong — is of continually increasing importance as a civilized population increases in density. The principle which guides in doing it cannot be conveniently explained here, but the subject is approached in the section (s. 6, p. 47), relating to the power of growth in the common law. Thirdly, the rights in respect of demand and supply of labour are in a sense reciprocal — that is, obstruction of supply must be an obstruction in the way of the demand, which would have been supplied but for the obstruction, and was not. Still there may be direct obstruction to the party supplying labour which may or may not be an obstruction to the party demanding it, according to the possibility of obtaining a supply elsewhere. Fourthly, the means of obstruction may be acts unlawful in themselves, but the intrinsic unlaw- fulness is irrelevant to their unlawfulness from obstructing the free course of trade. This propo- sition involves considerations of much complexity. I have above attempted to give one example of Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. i6 THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. Objcciiovs n/isivered. (Section V. p. 42.; my meaning, and I will only add a caution lest zeal for freedom to honest industry should result in giving facility to artful malignity. Fifthly, the obstruction may be caused by the use of words operating to alienate workmen or employers from each other. The use of such words for the purpose of obstructing trade may be either lawful or unlawful, upon the principles in accordance with which defamation injurious to character may be justifiable or not. Such defa- mation may be justified either for the protection of a lawful interest belonging to the defamer, or for the performance of a moral duty by him, provided always that the defamation be uttered without malice — that is, without a corrupt motive. The application of these principles has caused endless discussion, but enough has been said in this place to exemplify the considerations in- volved in a legal proceeding for an alleged nuisance b5^ obstruction of freedom to trade. Objection has been made that the principles above laid down are not correct, being incon- sistent with the restraints on barristers, phy- sicians, and the like, and also with the restraints on employers and others under the Factory Acts. An answer to this is attempted in the section on this subject. TO TRADE UNIONS. 17 As to competition. It was said above that the question of unlawfulness arises when the transactions of the union are supposed to operate in restraint of trade : and when the action of the union is directed to the purpose either of raising wages in the case of working men, or of lowering wages in the case of employers, by any restraint upon freedom of competition, the question of unlawful restraint of trade has arisen. To this question the presumption is that the answer should be in the affirmative ; but the answer cannot be certain unless the facts are speci- fied, for this presumption may be rebutted by the circumstances, as is above suggested in reference to other alleged nuisances from obstruction. . Wages are said to rise and fall by the action of competition between labour and capital, and this may be true in ultimate results. But the competition to which the law for securing a free course for trade relates, is the competition be- tween working men themselves where the supply of labour exceeds the demand, and between em- ployers where the demand for labour of a given kind in a given locality exceeds the supply. It seems inaccurate to describe the competi- tion to be between the capitalist and the labourer; because the capitalist, in a stricter sense, is occupied in lending value at interest propor- tionate to risk, and is indifferent about wages C Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. Competi- tion. THE LA W RE LA TING Chaf. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. and profits, production and prices. In a wider sense, many of the employed are owners of some capital in the shape of tools and other equip- ment. Many of the employers are borrowers only, and poorer than the employed ; and the notion that employers are rich and powerful, and oppressive because they are employers, is unfounded. Furthermore, it seems inaccurate to contra- distinguish labourers or working men from capi- talists or employers, as if they were separate classes ; for both classes labour, and the labour of the brain for the employing class may be immeasurably more severe than the labour of the muscles of motion for the working class. All must labour by themselves or others, capital being past labour accumulated. The accumu- lated stores of the mental labour of past ages exceed in value all money. These stores must be used by the employer in the degree required by his business ; but muscular action may be supplied with very slight recourse to accumu- lated knowledge in many departments of labour. There is no hardship in labour, unless excessive ; it is the condition for the existence of happiness universally, and in moderation is a grand boon. It is also true, in one sense, that all employed are employers, and all employers are employed, according to the relation of the person in respect TO TRADE UNIONS. 19 of whom the term is apphed to some other person with whom he is compared. I do not advert further to competition be- tween classes, because the law is concerned directly with the rights of individuals, and only indirectly with the interests of classes, and be- cause the free course for trade secured by law is a free course for each individual to dispose of his labour or his capital according to his own choice. Moreover, the attempt to restrain trade in the relation between employers and employed begins for the most part with attempts in the way of combination, whereby the individuals of one class, either employers or labourers, attempt to restrain others of the same class from direct competition with themselves. Up to a certain point the attempt may be lawful. The question is thus raised. What is the point at which the attempt begins to be unlawful } And the answer, I submit, should be — When unlawful coercion is attempted to be put upon the will of any indi- vidual in disposing of his labour or his capital. It is not easy to give a definition which shall include every kind of "unlawful coercion :" but it seems clear that the causing of damage to the person or the property or the estimation of the party to be coerced, cither by unlawful action, or by falsehood (including all decejation), C 2 Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. Unlaivfiil Ol'stntction of Trade. THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. RigJii to Free Course for Trade in I^abour. or by causing the fear of such damage from unlawful action or falsehood, or by obstructing the party who is to be coerced in the exercise of any right connected with trade by unlawful action or by falsehood — for the purpose of sway- ing or defeating his will in disposing of his labour or his capital — would be instances of unlawful coercion, and so of unlawful restraint of trade. I submit that there may also be unlawful ob- struction to the free course of trade without any such unlawful coercion as is above described. Restraint of the free course for trade in labour by acts of molestation or obstruction, which are not otherwise unlawful, but which operate as a hindrance to the exercise of a trade, and which are done for the purpose of such hin- drance without justification, seems to me, as above stated, to be an actionable wrong. The Act 6 Geo. IV. c. 129 is, in my opinion, decla- ratory of the common law as to the offence, and operative only to make a summary remedy. The statute declares acts of molestation or obstruc- tion, as well as acts of violence, intimidation, and threats, to be an offence: but of this more when we come to the statutes. Furthermore, I think that there may also be unlawful restraint of trade without coercion by unlawful means, and without such obstruction or molestation as is last above mentioned. TO TRADE UNIONS. I assume that the employer and the employed have each a right to a free course for trade in labour, as above described. The supply of labour to the employer is stopped if the working-man chooses to stop ; and assuming for the present that his act is lawful whenever he freely chooses so to do, still a party who induces him so to do may, in so doing (as it seems to me) infringe the right of the employer to a free course for the supply of labour. I take the case of money paid to the working-man to induce him to stop, in which the motive for so paying is malice towards the employer — that is, some corrupt or spiteful motive. I put aside money so paid from a motive of supposed interest, as in the case of some strikes, and assume it to be paid for the sole purpose of ruining the employer or destroying his manufacture. A question is thus raised, Does the law allow it } I think not. A stop in the supply of labour is obviously a damage in every trade ; the causing of the stop is a restraint of trade ; and all re- straint of trade is, as above stated, presumed to be unlawful until the contrary be shown. Such a stop may be lawful, as for instance, where the money is paid by a competitor offering higher wages to obtain workmen ; but in the case sup- posed the money is paid " not to work " for a particular party, for the sole purpose of causing Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. THE LA W RELA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Frse Course for Trade in Labour. damage to that party whose supply is thus stopped. If the party paying for such a stop attempts to rebut the presumption of unlawful- ness by alleging an honest purpose, the question of motive is the issue ; and if the motive is found to be malicious, it seems to me to accord with principle that he should be found guilty of a wrong and made liable to damages. If two or more combined for the purpose of so causing damage, the combination would, I be- lieve, be a crime. Other cases may be put of a wrong inflicted by paying money for the pur- pose of buying absence in order to cause damage to a third party. If a person would be material as a witness in an approaching trial, would it not be a wrongful obstruction to the course of justice for the adverse party to pay him to conceal himself so that he could not be summoned to attend, although no duty to attend would be created before service of a summons .'' And so, before the statutes against corrupt prac- tices at elections, would not an action have lain for paying a voter to be out of the way at polling-time .-' What has been said of gifts of money for the purpose of stopping supply of labour is true, mutatis imitaiidis, of persuasion for the same purpose. The law relating to comments on the conduct TO TRADE UNIONS. 23 of men in public capacities affords an analogy. Such comments, however defamatory, are justi- fied, if the motive of the writer be not corrupt : but if a private enemy of such a man were to hire a defaming writer to write him down, and such a hiring was in proof, the motive would be corrupt, and the justification would fail ; and any of the parties to such defamation would be liable in an action for damages. So he who attempts to justify a stop in the supply of labour to another, by persuading workmen to leave him for the sole purpose of gratifying his spite against the employer, ought to be made liable — and, I believe, is liable at common law — for the damage caused by such persuasion. This is enough to indicate my opinion as to the effect of the common law prohibition against restraint upon trade in labour either by un- lawful coercion or, in some instances, by other means. As to combination, each person has a right to choose whether he will labour or not, and also to choose the terms on which he will consent to labour, if labour be his choice. The power of choice in respect of labour and terms, which one person may exercise and declare singly, many after consultation may exercise jointly, and they may make a simultaneous declaration of their Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. Combina- tion. 24 THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade iti Labour. choice, and may lawfully act thereon for the immediate purpose of obtaining the required terms ; but they cannot create any mutual obli- gation having the legal effect of binding each other not to work or not to employ unless upon terms allowed by the combination. Any arrange- ment for that purpose, whatever may be its purport or form, does not bind as an agreement, but is illegal, though not unlawful, on account of restraint of trade, and therefore void. Every party to it, who chooses to put an end to it, is thenceforward as free to claim his own terms for his own labour as if such arrangement had never been made ; and any attempt to enforce, by unlawful coercion, performance of any such supposed agreement, against a party who chooses to break from it and labour or con- tract for labour upon different terms, is an attempt to obstruct him in the lawful exercise of his right to freedom to trade ; and is thus a private wrong. It is also a violation of a duty towards the public — that is to say, of the duty to abstain from obstructing the exercise of the right to the free course of trade. A person can neither alienate for a time his free- dom to dispose of his own labour or his own capital according to his own will (see Hilton V. Eckersley, 6 Ell. & Bl. 47), nor alienate such freedom generally and make himself a slave (see TO TRADE UNIONS. 25 the argument of Hargrave in the Negro Som- mersett's case, 20 State Trials, 23) ; it follows that he cannot transfer it to the governing body of a union. The reported cases exemplifying the applica- tion of these principles of common law are not numerous, because for some centuries statutes were passed with the intent of regulating the rate of wages, and the mode of conducting business, by the interference of the magistrate. But the law of this subject was much debated in Hilton v. Eckersley in the Queen's Bench and in the Exchequer Chamber ; and the inalienability of the right to freedom in dis- posing of labour or capital according to the will of the individual owner was there affirmed. In that case several employers had mutually bound themselves under a penalty to carry on their respective concerns according to the will of the majority. The bond was held void for restraint of trade ; and the opinion of Erie, J., to the effect that capitalists had the same rights in respect of capital as working men had in respect of labour, and that working men had a right to make any agreement for transferring to others the disposal of their labour which they chose (meaning an agreement of binding force) for the purpose of raising wages, was held to Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. Hilton V. Eckersley. 26 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade in Labour. R. V Row- lands, and R. V. Dnf- d. [Ap- pendix A , be wrong. It follows that expressions to the same effect supposed to have been used by him in R. V. Rowlands and R. v. Duffield (5 Cox C.C. 436 and 404) were also incorrect. These expres- sions seem to have been founded on a miscon- struction of the 6 Geo. IV. c, 129, s. 4 ; whereas, although by that section it was enacted that com- binations and agreements for raising or lowering wages should be exempted from criminal respon- sibility, yet they were not made lawful.^ The cases of R. v. Rowlands and R. v. Duffield are noticed in the Appendix. These are the general principles in accord- ance with which unreasonable restraint of trade in disposing of labour or capital is prohibited, and freedom in disposing thereof is maintained. The practical application of these principles lies in indictment for violation of duty towards the public, and in action for violation of a private right, according to the circumstances of the case in which a remedy for a wrong is sought. I do not attempt to follow the application of these principles to supposed cases any farther, on account of the difficulty of com- 1 A judgment for the plaintiff in Hilton v. Eckersley might probably have been supported on the ground that the circum- stances of society which gave occasion for some of the rules of the common law and many of the statutes against combinations of working men were changed, the common law being in a state of perpetual growth : cessanie ratioiic, cessat lex. The law is as the judges declare it to be. TO TRADE UNIONS. 27 prising all the relevant facts in the supposition. Men having the qualities requisite for dealing with legal principles — that is, who are qualified to assist either in administering the law as attorneys, advocates, or judges, or in amending the law as legislative advisers — would, I expect, have power to apply them. The requisite qualities are — First, a general knowledge of the body of the law in its organic entirety, by which the relation of each part to the living body is perceived, in analogy with which the relation of a living branch to its parent tree is understood. For example, if action lies, there must have been a right and a violation of it — that is, a wrong ; if indictment lies, there must have been a duty towards the public and a breach thereof. Secondly, a capacity for extracting principles from adjudications, and raising them by ab- straction to a wide extension, and afterwards perceiving their effect pervading subordinate principles. And thirdly, sagacity in taking from the multitude of facts which must be always co- existing at the time and place when and where a complainant alleges he was wronged, the facts relevant to show the right and the violation thereof, and also the facts relevant to show the limitation of the supposed right within the degree Chap. I. Common Law. § 3. Right to Free Course for Trade hi Labour. 28 THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common Law. §3. Right to hrce Cojirse ^or Trade in Labour. §4- Pro- ceedings for Violation of the Right to Freedom in Trade. (-o- cecdings for Violation of the Right to Freedom its. Trade. Conspiracy in general. THE LAW RELATING Char I. Common Law. M- Pro- ceedings/or l^iolation of ilu- Right to Freedom hi. Trade. De Beren- ger's case. R. V. Turner. not being a person ; but there are duties towards the public of great importance, and it is con- venient to speak of the pubhc having rights correlating with those duties. Adopting this form of speaking, it may be said that wrongs become crimes by reference to the import- ance of the public right violated thereby ; but v/hatever be the essence of crime, it is certain that a combination to commit a crime is a crime. There seems also to be authority for saying that a combination to violate a private right, in which the public has a sufficient interest, is a crime, such a violation being an actionable wrong. De Berenger's case (3 M. & S. 67), if I understand it aright, is an example. He combined with others to spread at the Stock Exchange a false report of the death of Buonaparte, for the purpose of raising the price of stocks and selling at the rise. In my opinion, he violated by the use of falsehood the private right of the purchasers in the market to buy at the price settled by competition ; and the Court decided that the public has an interest in the security of the public funds suf- ficient to make such a combination to effect a private wrong a crime. The limitation exclud- ing from this category of crimes the class of injuries in which the public has not a sufficient interest appears from the case of R. v. Turner (13 East, 228), deciding that a combination for rO TRADE UNIONS, 33 the purpose of taking hares unlawfully is not indictable for that reason ; and this limitation is sanctioned by Lord Campbell in Hilton v. Eckersley (6 Ell. & Bl. 47), by his saying " that the decision was wrong in respect of fact, for it appeared in the statement of the facts that the defendants were armed to resist the owner of the hares, and that it was therefore a combination for the purpose of a breach of the peace, and for that reason a crime." This correction of the judgment in respect of fact is an implied assent to its correctness in point of law if the facts had been as they were assumed to be. A com- bination for wrong gives facilities to wrongdoers, as above stated ; so that a combination to trespass may with reason be held to be a crime, although the trespasser, if single, would be liable to action only and not to indictment. There are other cases of conspiracy not so specially defined. The guilt of conspiracy may arise from simul- taneity of action which an individual could not incur by himself, as a combination of a crowd for the purpose of so using a highway as to do harm to other passengers. There are also public interests of great im- portance in respect of which some combinations for the piu'pose of violating the public rights therein arc crimes, altliough such violations by D Chap. 1. Comniun Law. § 4. Pro- cci'iliiigs for Viola tiou of the Right to Freedom in Trade. 34 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. I. Common Law. § 4- /'''(;- ceedhigsfor I'ioliition pf the Right to Frecdon in Trade. R. V. M.iw- bey. an individual alone may not be always indic- table. Justice, morality, polity, and trade are examples of such public interests. Combinations to pei"vert justice by deception are criminal ; and the statute of Edward I. against conspiracies to maintain false pleas is declaratory of the common law on that subject. R. V. Mawbey (6 T. R. 619) is an example of this crime, where the defendants (two justices) com- bined for the purpose of deceiving the Quarter Sessions by a false certificate of road repair. As to morality, the law coincides therewith, although it does not vindicate every breach thereof; and there is a class of cases where the interference of the law is supported on the ground of morality. In this class are the com- binations for deluding women into unchastity, either by aggravated seduction (see R. v. Lord Grey, 9 State Trials, 127), or by deceptive forms of marriage (see the cases collected in Russell on Crimes, by Greaves, b. v. c. 2, vol. iii. pp. 130 et seq. 4th ed.). In this class also is included the case of R. v. Delaval and others (3 Burr. 1435), where the defendant Delaval combined with the master of a girl apprenticed to learn singing to take an assignment of her apprenticeship for the purpose of teaching and seducing her, and they were convicted of conspiracy. The ground of the decision is not given, as no objection was TO TRADE UNIONS. 35 made. But it cannot be disputed that such conduct was a breach of the duty created by an ordinary deed of apprenticeship towards the apprentice and her parents, and so a personal wrong and a civil injury. It was also a vio- lation of the public interest in the chastity of the women who are inclined to be chaste, to make the rights conferred by law on masters subserve the purpose of doing this wrong to an apprentice. The combinations for seditious purposes are violations of the public interest in maintaining the polity established by law. Of these cases no explanation is required. I come now to conspiracies connected with trade. Some of the lav^^s which affect the distribution of commodities, and make provision in order that supply and demand may meet and deal upon the terms obtained by free competition, have been above referred to. The laws affecting the production of com- modities make similar provision, mutatis mutan- dis, in order that all the parties concerned in the process required for the production of a saleable product may deal as to labour upon the terms obtained by free competition. Such obstruction as is above described to free competition in D 2 Chap. I. Common Law. § 4- Pro- ccdings/or Viola tiim of the Right to Freedom in Trade. Conspiracies connected with Trade. 36 THE LA W RE LA TING Chap. I. Common La»v, §4- Pro- ceedi'igs for Violation of the Riglit to Freedom in Trade. disposing of labour or capital is an unlawful restraint of trade, and a combination so to re- strain trade by preventing free competition is the crime of conspiracy, being a violation of a private right in which the public has an interest, and also a violation of a duty towards the public. It seems essential that the terms obtained b}- free competition should prevail consistenth* throughout all the processes involved in pro- duction, seeing that it is commercially useless if it will not fetch a remunerative price after paying the cost of production, the amount of which cost depends on the terms obtained by competition. The employer has to go through many pro- cesses of cost and risk : he has to deal with the landlord for premises, with the capitalist for money and fixed capital, and with artisans for work. The employed has to take the wages for which he consents to work without the same risk or cost. In all these processes the law provides for the action of free competition, making a combination in restraint of trade by so obstruct- ing free competition, as is above described, the crime of conspiracy. In relation to j^roduction the combinations of the employed to obstruct free competition amongst the working class for wages are more frequent than combinations of employers to obstruct free competition amongst themselves. TO TRADE UNIONS. 37 The interest of the employed in a uniform rate of wages is more common to the class in general than the interest of the employers in any at- tempt to make a uniform scale of prices or profits. Moreover, the employed are a more numerous class, and by reason of closer com- panionship in factories and the like, and more constant interchange of mind there, have more facilities for acting in concert. These conside- rations may account for more frequent pro- ceedings against working men than against employers, without imputing partiality in the administration of the law. The tendency to combine for the purpose of raising or lowering wages appears from the manifold statutes passed for the purpose of ad- justing a current rate of wages on some basis other than free competition. These statutes have long since been repealed. While they were in force they tended to prevent a resort to the common law remedy for conspiracy, and the records of proceedings under the common law against conspirators for the purpose of restrain- ing freedom for labour are not numerous ; but .still there are authorities sufficient to show what the law is in this matter. In the collections of precedents for indict- ments for conspiracy to raise wages, in violation Chap. I. Common Law. § 4. Prt>- ceedings for Violation 0/ the Right to Frecdotn in Trade. [c^ Indict- ment for con- spiracy. 38 THE LA W RELA TING Chai>. I. Common Law. § 4. Pro- ceedings/or Violation 0/ tlie Right to Freedom in Trade. Hilton V. Eckersley. of the statutes fixing a maximum, which are given in Wentworth and Chitty, there are counts for combining not to work for less than the required wages, founded on the common law prohibition against restraint of trade ; but the most important authority is Hilton v. Eckersley (6 Ell. & Bl. 47) before mentioned. There an agreement by employers to carry on business as the majority should direct was decided to be in restraint of trade at common law, and illegal and void, though exempt from prosecution under 6 George IV. c. 129, as mentioned above. The case is cited here for the sake of the judgment of Crompton, J., who held that such an agree- ment would be " indictable at common law, as tending directly to impede and interfere with the free course of trade and manufacture," and to take away " the freedom of action of an indivi- dual to carry on his trade according as it may be for his interest or that of the public." He dwelt also on the mischief that would follov.- if parties should give up the right of judging for themselves, and place themselves under the dictation either of a majority or of a committee of delegates. Crompton, J. was remarkable for learning, depth, and acuteness, and was painfully conscientious about speaking accurately when he spoke judicially. I believe also that he never recognised the notion that the common law TO TRADE UNIONS. 39 adapts itself by a perpetual process of growth to the perpetual roll of the tide of circum- stances as society advances. His judgment in this case is direct to the point that an agree- ment for any coercion whatever, restraining the free-will of each party by the will of the whole, is an illegal restraint of trade, and indictable at common law. Other judges held the bond to be illegal, but reserved their opinion on the point of criminality. Erie, J. held it to be legal ; and his opinion was adjudged to be wrong, as above mentioned. Walsby v. Anley (30 L. J. M. C. 121) is also a decision bearing on this point. Walsby com- bined with other workmen to leave the employ of Anley simultaneously, unless he discharged certain workmen who were working under a declaration which they objected to. They thus conspired to coerce his will in the exercise of his right to a free course of trade in respect of hiring and discharging. Crompton and Hill, J.J. held that this was a conspiracy indictable at common law. The question was raised by an appeal against a conviction for endeavouring by threats to force the emplo}'er to limit the nuni- ber of his workmen, under 6 Geo. IV. c. 129, s. 3. The words of alleged threat were : " Unless the men who are working under the declaration be discharged, we cease to work immediately." Chap. I. Common Law. §4- Pro- ceediii~s/or Violaiioii of the Right to Freedom in Ti-acie. iralshy V. Anley. 40 THE LA IV RE LA TING Chap. I. Common §4- Pro- ceedings for Violation of the Right to Freedom in Trade. R. V. Maiv- bcy. The objection to the conviction was, that this was no threat, because each had a right to leave singly, and it was contended that it followed that all had a right to leave simultaneously. The objection w^as overruled by all the judges, but on different grounds ; by the Chief Justice on the ground that a notice of an intended simultaneous stop of work, with the prohibited intent, was a criminal threat within the statute. But I cite the case here for the sake of the judgments of Crompton and Hill, J. J., who held that the threat must be of an illegal act, and that a com- bination for a simultaneous stop of work for the purpose of annoying the master was an obstruc- tion to the free course of trade, and a crime ; and Crompton, J. refers to his judgment in Hilton V. Eckersley, and affirms its correctness, notwithstanding the objections thereto by Mr. Longe in his pamphlet on the Law of Strikes} It should be noted that the simultaneity of the leaving makes the damage, and that the act of one cannot cause that damage. The dictum of Grose, J. in R. v. Mawbey (6 T. R. 6^)6), relating to the criminality of combinations to raise wages, was relevant only for the purpose of establishing that the guilt of conspiracy is complete by the agreement. '^ An Inquiry info the Z.7w of Sln'h's. By F. D. Longe. Cambridge and London, i860. TO TRADE UNIONS. 41 The case had no connexion with wages, as explained above. In R. V. Journeymen Tailors of Cambridge (8 Mod. 10) the conspiracy was to refuse to work at a less sum per day than was demanded, being at a higher rate than the maximum of wages fixed under the statute 5 Eliz. c. 4. The dicta in the last two cases, that acts lawful for one may become indictable if more than one combine to commit them, Avere not pertinent to the adjudication then being made. The judges do not refer to examples, and although the proposition may be true of cases where simultaneity is the essence of the crimi- nality of the act, I cannot discover any other cases in which it would be true. From the authorities referred to it appears that the crime of conspiracy consists of two elements — namely, an intention, and an agree- ment by two or more tc execute it ; th^it an in- tention to use such coercion as is above described to be unlawful, against any person in the exercise of his right to freedom to trade, is sufficient as to one element of conspiracy ; and that the making of the agreement to execute the inten- tion completes the offence. The mere intention, without some act equivalent to an attempt to execute it, is not sufficient, but the outward act by which mutual consent to an agreement is interchanged is sufficient to complete the offence. Chap. I. Common Law. §4- Pro- ceedings/or Violation of the Right to Freedom in Trade. R. V. Jour- neymen Tailors of Cainhridge. 42 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. I. Common Law. §4- fro- cecdiiigs fo?- If this reasoning is correct, the common law in force since the statute of 6 George IV. secures to every person freedom to follow his own will "■ioiaUoTcf as to working and employment, and also as the Right to , ,..'.,, Freednmin to combuimg With othcrs HI rcspcct ot wages Trade. and hours, and for all other lawful purposes ; but he has no right to use unlawful means, either by himself or in combination with others, in order to coerce the will of another party to prevent him from working or employing as he may choose ; and probably he has no right to apply the power of a combination for the purpose either of malicious damage or of unjust extortion, although he uses no unlawful means except combining to obstruct the free course of trade, in order to effect such purpose. § 5. statu- table aiid Professional Restraints of Freedom to Labour. V, Statutable and Pi'ofessional Rcstravits of Freedom to Labour. — Two objections have been offered to the correctness of the principle that every employer and every working man has a right, as between him and his fellow subjects, to act according to his own will in disposing of his own capital or his own labour as far as is compatible with the rights of others : first, be- cause the law has put several restraints upon this freedom ; and secondly, because in the pro- fessions of a physician and an advocate usage has put some restraints on this freedom in recrard to the amount of fees. TO TRADE UNIONS. 43 As to tlie first objection, one answer is con- tained in the words used in defining the principle, by which its apphcation is hmited to the right of one subject as against anotJier subject. All rights are created by law, and are regu- lated by law : the right to the freedom as above described, although protected from violation by other subjects, is still regulated under the law. The law restrains the working mian of every rank from many kinds of work unless he has a legal qualification. Ke may not v/ork in certain medical, legal, militar}^, and nautical capacities, unless qualified according to law. These are examples of restraints imposed by law to save the public from damage by reason of want of skill. There are also restraints imposed by law to save the party restrained from damage by reason of his own ignorance or helplessness, such as restraints on women and children from excess of labour under the Factory Acts, or restraints on working men in some deleterious trades from sacrifice of health. Restraints also from trade unless qualified by apprenticeship are restraints under the law. So the law restrains the capi- talist from disposing of his capital for purposes which violate legality, morality, public policy, and the like. Restraints may also be m:iposed by law on parties incapable from infancy or mental disease of managing their own affairs for their own sake. Chap. I. Common Law. § 5. SiatH- table and Pmfcsslonnl Rrstrnints of Freedom to Labour. (.,) Re- straiiits by laiu, as by Factory A cts. 44 THE LA W RELA TING Common Law. § 5. Stain- laOie and Profcssioial Restraints of Freedom to Labour. m Profess- ional fees. These restraints by law are distinct from re- straints by the will of another subject. The fullest freedom under the law as between him and his fellow subjects is compatible with count- less restraints imposed by law for the benefit of his fellow subjects individually, or of the public generally, or of himself. The right to this freedom for the capitalist and the working man is part of the right to property and personal security, and is subject to analogous restraints. It is analogous to the right to passage according to will on a highway : generally speaking, all have it ; but an individual may be restrained by lawful imprisonment, and all may be restrained when the law authorises a stop of passage. Some unions attempt to restrain the freedom of the members either without authority of law, as by agreements which are void, because con- trary to public jDolicy ; or in violation of law, as where rules in restraint of trade are enforced by unlawful means. There is no analogy be- tween these restraints and such restraints under the law as are above mentioned. The second objection, founded on the usage relating to the fees for physicians and advo- cates, has been applied both for the purpose of impeaching the principle of freedom for the course of trade, and for the purpose of justify- ine the action of those unions which fix a rO TRADE UNIONS. 45 minimum wage for an artisan; but whatever | Chap. i be the purpose for which the objection is used, ' La"- '" § 5. StatK- ofessioiial Restraints of Frecttoin to Labour. it seems to be founded on a misconception, and to be irrelevant to the law relating toj^rif"""^ trade unions. The action of unions, so far as it excludes non-unionists from work, and requires forj unionists wages to a certain amount, is founded ! on a supposed monopoly of a given kind of work in a given district. All such work is assumed to be the property of the union : if all the workmen who can supply the work are in the union, the monopoly is secured ; and the usual action has been to increase washes and decrease work until a maximum amount of wages has been extracted from the' employ- ers, and the equal distribution of the minimum amount of work secured for each member. This action has no analogy to the usage of the two professions above named. The exclu- sion of unqualified men from practice is not for the sake of giving a monopoly of practice to the qualified, as explained above. It is not in order to limit number, but to secure efficiency. Neither have the physicians or barristers any combined action for extracting from patients or suitors the maximum of money for the minimum of work, and distributing it equally among all the members of those two profes- 46 THE LA W RELA TING Chat. I. Common Law. § 5. Statu- table and Professional Restraints of Freedom to Labour. sions. It is clear that the usual amount of a professional fee is settled on a different principle from that which regulates the wages for service. In these two professions service is in law gra- tuitous, and is often so in fact. It cannot be estimated at any market rate : the external act of service may be almost imperceptible, indeed it may lie in a u'ord ; and yet the value of it to the recipient may be immeasurably great. Pro- bably bargaining in each case would be un- pleasant to both parties, and a settlement by custom is preferred. Whatever may be the reason for the usage, enough has been said to show that it is founded on a principle different from that by which unions seek to regulate wages. I would only add a reference to Ken- nedy V. Broun et ux. (32 L. J., N. S., C. P. 137), where the right of an advocate to sue for re- muneration was negatived : the reason given for the adjudication accords with this explana- tion. If it should appear to any that a party making a contract for his labour is coerced if the opposite party require him either to perform his contract, or to pay damages for the breach of it, it would not be superfluous to remark that freedom to dispose of labour consists in freedom to contract for disposing of it. Labour, unless gratuitous, can only be disposed of by TO TRADE UNIONS. 47 hire, so that a contract for hire is an appHca- lloii of the principle, not an exception from it : restraint arises when the party is restrained from using his own will in making a contract for [ Proj, his own labour. The same observation is true of any restraint supposed to be created by partnership. The restraint on property is created by an assign- ment of private property to the partnership ; and the restraint on service, if any, is created by the contract for agency involved in the contract of partnership. VI. The Roots and Groivth of the Coiiiinon Laiv. — There are some relations between man and man which do not change, such as birth; and the rules of law relating thereto do not change. There are other relations which are perpetually changing as society progresses, and the conflicts of rights caused by this perpetual process of change is the subject of a perpetual process of adjustment, according to principles contained in the common law. The serfs and copyholders of the middle ages passed through many variations of rights, as well at common law as by statute, before they became enfran- chised electors. Rights in respect of contracts, restraint of trade, combination, the relation between em- Chap. I. Cnmiiioii Lavv. . 5. Statu- table and o/t'ssiotial Restraints of Freedom to Labour. % 6. The Roots and Gro'^vtli of the Co)iunon La:v. THE LA W RELA TING Char I. Common Law. §6, The Roots and Grouitk of the Common ployer and employed, and some kinds of nuisances, afford examples of perpetual change. An attempt to adjust them by statute may succeed, if the authors and interpreters of the statute understand the principles of the com- mon la'w, and in some degree incorporate them. Without that process the interpretation of the words of a statute merely by a dictionary leads often to unsatisfactory results. Even if the statute is well drawn, society soon progresses beyond it, and the need of the principles of the common law is constantly renewed. I therefore offer a few words on the power of growth in the common law. I do so with misgiving, having no judicial authority for my opinion that I know of. Every rule of the common law ought to be applied with some limitation of reasonableness in degree. The relations of ideas of number, measure, and weight may be expressed in un- limited terms with absolute certaint}- ; but it is not so with the relations of the actions of man upon man. Those relations cannot be defined till the laws of matter, and also the laws of mind, are within the limits of certain knowledge, and till social progress is stopped. Definite rules therefore may not be expected. In the mean- time life multiplies, proximity increases, and each man mouM become a nuisance to his neigh- TO TRADE UNIONS. 49 hour in respect (among manifold other matters) of air and water, labour and capital, production and distribution, if a perpetual process of ad- justment was not in constant action. This •adjustment is effected by the principles of the Common Law. These principles originate practically from the people. Proximity leads to mutual help in a known course of business ; a known course of business involves the recognition of some estab- lished principles. These principles may be acted on long before a complete language is framed. A course of business without a verbal law is equivalent to living law ; a verbal law not in accordance with the course of business cannot be practically enforced. In all assemblies of free men each man has authority in proportion as his mind is noble. The test of nature's nobility is industry. In agriculture, trade, and manufacture, the men of most influence are in effect seers, and the seers establish the course of business which is con- sidered by them the most expedient at the time ; and in case of dispute the same seers are trusted as arbitrators to apply the principles involved in the course of business. The prin- ciples are applied at first in the concrete ; gradually they grow into rules of wider appli- cation, and words grow appropriate for their E Comnn 11 Law. § 6. r!ie Roots find Growth of the Com7Jio7i Law. !;o THE LA W RELA TING Common Law. §6. The Roots and Growth of tlie Coiitino.i L.itu. expression ; and the judiciary men and the legislative men adopt them. Throughout this process the rules practically originate from the people.^ In a mass of free people the unso- phisticated majority, according to experience, are certain to intend to side with the kind and true against the false and malicious : the com- pound of the kind and true being the just. This process has in all mercantile countries been in constant action, as the law merchant is in its theory adjusted by the usage of merchants. The same process was in constant action in the Saxon county-courts presided over by the sheriff. The probi ct Icgalcs Jiomincs attending on the county-court were men of practical business engaged in useful industry, and living in the neighbourhood. From them the jury- men were selected ; and the jury so taken were judges both of the law and of the fact, the sheriff having power to keep order on the trial, but having no power to guide the decision. The law must therefore have been found by the jury in the traditions of the course of the business in which the contention arose, and in their own sense of right. So far as rules of conduct for practical people are concerned, it matters not whether justice is 1 See Savigny's Trait J de D^-oit romai?t, translated by Gue- noux, lib. i. cap. 2, ss. 7 and 9, Droit populaire, -j TO TRADE UNIONS. 51 supposed to have its source in inductive search after utiHty, or in an intuitive perception of right to be tested by utility, inasmuch as utility and right in this sense lead to a similar course of action. One man obeys conscience. tested by utility; another takes utility alone for a guide. But if the origin of the principles of the common law is to be traced beyond their practical existence, they seem to originate from conscience — that is, from the same power which has made the majority of all free men of all ages and languages to have a perception of that which they feel to be just, and which they admire for itself, and assume to be useful till the contrary be proved. And among such free men some are pre-eminently gifted with this perception of the just. The jurists whose words are recorded in the civil law rely on their own sense of right where an opinion is adopted because " cEqiinm esse miJii videtiirr The words of these men would not have been handed down if they had merely ex- pressed their intuitions before their highest facul- ties had been trained by long and painful efforts both to understand the relations of man to man, and the words of wide extension expressive of those relations, and also to know how far those relations had been so adjusted by the men who had gone before as that their adjustment had E 2 Common Law. §6. The Roots and ■ Growth 0/ the CoiiuHon Law. 52 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. I ConiPKjn Law. §6. The Roots and Croiuth of the Common Law. been adopted into the usages of the people and grown into law ; such adoption being the process by which living law grows. So the jurists whose writings are authority for international law relied in solving a new question on their own intuition of right, giving as their reason, " Quia aqnuvi est J' So, also, in England, the Chancellors who originated equitable rules overruling law saw, by their intuitive perception, the iniquity of the law to be overruled, and introduced the remedy ; and amongst the Judges at Common Law, Hale, Holt, and Mansfield may be taken as examples of men who by the exercise of the same intuitive perception became emi- nent. They were masters of the learning of their predecessors ; their commissions ran then as nov/, "to do what to justice appertained, ac- cording to the laws and customs of England ; " and although they maintained in accordance with those laws and customs some of the feudal ])rinciples established after the Conquest, which had survived to their time, yet when new relations in social progress raised new ques- tions, and feudality had either expired or was irrelevant, they decided according to their own intuition of ju.stice : and they have their eminence because their intuitions have accorded with those of the strong men in the generations that have TO TRADE UNIONS. 53 succeeded, Mansfield takes rank as a benefactor of mankind ; and the recommendation of Junius that he should be impeached for in- troducing notions of substantial justice to modify some supposed rules of common law which worked iniquity, is evidence of his title to that rank. I have said so much of the common law in general, as well as of those principles thereof which are relevant to trade unions, because the power of the law lies in the respect of the people for it, and I believe that the common law will be regarded as a valuable inheritance by all who understand its principles, and can com- pare reasoning thereon with reasoning on the mere words of a statute. There is a description of the sources of the common law by Parke, B., in Mirehouse v. Rennell (i CI. & Finn. 546), which is superior to any that I can write. Lord Coke, also, has given an account of the sources of the common law in Co. Litt. lib. I pass these descriptions with the remark that they describe rather the places where the stream of the common law may be found flowing, than the place where the source rises or the root begins. Common Law §6. The Roots and Growth of the Common Law. In concluding this chapter, I would refer, forj the purpose of removing an unjust estimation 54 THE LAW RELATING TO TRADE UNIONS. Chap.I. Common Law. §6. The Roots and Crozvth of the Cotiniion Law. of law, to Hooker's words {Ecclcs. Pol. book i. ch. i.) on Government, as equally applicable to law : " He that goeth about to persuade a mul- titude, that they are not so well governed as they ought to be, shall never want attentive and favourable hearers ; because they know the manifold defects whereunto every kind of regiment is subject; but the secret lets and difficulties, which in public proceedings, are innumerable and inevitable, they have not ordi- narily the judgment to consider." And for the purpose of a just estimation of our Legislature since the Reform Act of 1832, I refer to Mr. Ludlow, who, in the book by him and Mr. Lloyd Jones on the Progress of the Working Class from 1832 to 1867, says that the legislation dur- ing that time has been "wholesome, stimulant, and beneficent," and justifies these words by specifying numerous statutes of enlightened wisdom and grand beneficent results, both to society in general and to the less rich part of it in particular ; wherefrom an ever-rising tide of improvement has been continuously flowing abroad upon the whole body of the people, without a suspicion of partiality for any class. CHAPTER 11. STATUTE LAW RELATING TO TRADE UNIONS. I. Statutes prior to 6 George IV. c. 129. — With respect to the statutes relating to trade unions, the 6 Geo. IV. c. 129, and the supple- mentary Act 22 Vict. c. 34, are the statutes now in force. The repealed legislation concerning trade and industry has been blamed for partiality. An examination of the grounds for blame would not now be worth the time, but I would sug- gest that persons are not justified in imputing it who have not examined the statutes by the light of the times in which they were passed, and are not sure that they could have proposed something more just and expedient if they had been then in Parliament. Much of this legislation was directed against combinations : it was supposed to contain more prohibitions than were required for the protection of person and property, and was all repealed either before Chap. II. Statutes. §1. Statutes firior to 6 Geo. IV. c. X2g. 56 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. II. Statutes. § I. Statute- frier to 6 Geo. IV. c. 129. !J2. r/ie Statute 6 Geo. ir. c. 129. or by the 5 Geo. IV, c. 95. The framers of this statute seem to have considered that the evils which pressed on the lower stratum of industry before the acts for the reform of Parliament, of the Poor Laws, and of the Corn Laws, would be alleviated by allowing them to combine for the obstruction of the free course of trade, assuming that the employers were richer, and oppressive because richer, and that the working men stood in no need of protection from each other ; assuming also that working men could violate the law for truth with im- punity, inasmuch as the statute authorised them to combine to induce other working men to break their contracts for service. The evils resulting in one year from this statute were sufficient to produce its repeal, and the sub- stitution of the 6 Geo. IV. c. 129. II. The Statute 6 George IV. c. 129. — This statute, like all others, must be construed with reference to the state of the law existing at the time of the enactment, and to the matters recited in the preamble. The principles of the common law existing at the time have been stated above. The preamble recites that the provisions of 5 Geo. IV. c. 95 were for the protection of the free employment of capital and labour, and for TO TRADE UNIONS. 57 the punishment of combinations interfering with such freedom by means of violence, threats, and intimidation, and that the provisions of that statute were not efifectual. It then recites that such combinations were dangerous to the tran- quillity of the country, and injurious to trade and commerce, and prejudicial to the interest of those concerned in them. It then recites the expedi- ency of making further provision as well for the security and personal freedom of individual workmen in the disposal of their skill and labour, as for the security of the property and persons of the masters and employers. These recitals show that the Legislature recog- nized a right to a free course for trade as therein and as herein described, and intended to create further security for the enjoyment of that right without partiality for any class. Furthermore, it may be noticed that although the 5 Geo. IV. c. 95 contained prohibitions against some combinations, and the attention of the Legislature was upon combinations in passing the 6 Geo. IV. c. 129, yet there is not only no prohibition therein against any kind of combination, but there are, on the contrary, two classes of combinations (those described in ss. 4 and 5) relating to wages, which are thereby rendered exempt from all liability whatever to penal consequences, as well under the common Chap. II. Statutes. 5 2. The Statute 6 Ceo IV. c. 129. THE LA IV RELA TING Chap. II Statutes. § 2. The Statute 6 Co. ir. c. 129. (a.) Tlie scc- tion of 6 Geo. IV. c. 129 contahi- ins: prohibi- tion. as under the statute law : it follows that all combinations and unions which are still unlawful conspiracies are unlawful by the operation of the common law. The 5 Geo. IV. c. 95 repealed so much of the common law as related to the criminality of the combinations exempted from punishment thereby; the 6 Geo. IV. c. 129 repealed the 5 Geo. IV. c. 95 entirely, and left the common law of conspiracy in force against all combina- tions in restraint of trade, the combinations exempted from penalty under ss. 4 and 5 alone excepted. It would be convenient to giv^e here the text of the third, fourth, and fifth sections of the statute 6 Geo. IV. c. 129; but as the im- portant section (the third) is long, and likely to confuse, I print these sections in an Appendix,^ together with section 44 of 18 & 19 Vict. c. 6'},, and section i of 22 Vict. c. 34, which are here- after referred to. The operative words of the third section of the Act of 6 Geo. IV. have been arranged with skill in a work on the Law of Combination ; ''^ and from it I gratefully borrow the subjoined 1 See Appendix B, p. 88. - Strikes and Lock-outs ; or, the Law of Combination. Barrister. London, 1867. By a TO TRADE UNIONS. 59 analysis, premising that the three classes of the offences created are indicated by Arabic numerals. Each offence consists of an action, together with an effect or purpose : the actions are indicated by letters of the alphabet, and the effects or purposes by Roman numerals. The offences prohibited by the 6 Geo. IV. c. 129 are all founded upon restraint of trade; and so far this statute declares the common law, while at the same time it adds some sum- mary remedies. In each of the three classes of offences the right to freedom in disposing of labour or capital according to the will of the individual is violated by some coercion, or attempt at coercion, of such will. In the first class the coercion is applied to the working man, in the third it is applied to the employer, and in the second it is applied indifferently to working men or employers in respect of their relation to some union. The third section enacts as follows : — " I. If any person, a. by violence to the person or property, b. or by molesting, c. or in any way obstructing another, i. forces or endeavours to force any journeyman, manufacturer, workman, or other person, hired or employed in any manufacture, trade, or business, Chap. II. Statutes. §2. The Statute b Ceo. II'. c. 129. 6o THE LA IV RE LA TING to depart from his hiring', employ- ment, or work, or to return his work before it is finished, ii. or prevents or endeavours to prevent any journeyman, manufacturer, work- man, or other person, not being hired or employed, from hiring himself to or from accepting work or employ- ment from any person ; every person so offending is liable to three months' imprisonment, with hard labour. 2. If any person, a. uses or employs violence to the per- son or property of another, b. or uses threats or intimidation, c. or molests, d. or in any way obstructs another, i. for the purpose of forcing or inducing such person to belong to any club or association, ii. or to contribute to any common fund, iii. or to pay any fine or penalty, iv. or on account of his not belonging to any particular club or association, V. or on account of his not having con- tributed or having refused to con- tribute to any common fund, or to pay any fine or penalty, TO TRADE UNIONS. 6r vi. or on account of liis not having com- plied, or of his refusing to comply with any rules, orders, resolutions, or regulations, made to obtain an ad- vance or to reduce the rate of wages, or to lessen or alter the hours of working, or to decrease or alter the quantity of work, or to regulate the mode of carrying on any manufac- ture, trade, or business, or the man- agement thereof ; every person so offending is liable to three months' imprisonment, with hard labour. '• 3. If any person, a. by violence to the person or property of another, b. or by threats or intimidation, c. or by molesting, d. or in any way obstructing another, i. forces, or endeavours to force, any manu- facturer, or person carrying on any trade or business, to make any alteration in his mode of regulating, managing, con- ducting, or carrying on such manufacture, trade, or business, or to limit the number of his apprentices, or the number or| Chap. I r. Statutes. § 2. TIu- Statute 6 Geo. ir. c. 129. 62 THE LA W RE LA TING Chai'. II. Statutes. § 2. The Statute 6 Geo. Il\ c". I2g. description of his journeymeii, workmen, or servants ; j every person so offending is liable to three months' imprisonment, with hard labour. " But (s. 4) no persons shall be punished who meet together for the sole purpose of consulting upon and determining the rate of wages or prices, which the persons present at the meeting, or any 1 of them, shall require or demand for their work ; or the hours for which they shall work in any manufacture, trade, or business. And (same sec.) no persons shall be punished who enter into any agreement, verbal or written, among them- selves, for the purpose of fixing the rate of wages or prices which the parties entering into the agree- ment, or any of them, shall demand for their work. " So much for the workmen. The 5 th section of the act relates to the masters. By that section the masters are not to be liable to any prosecution or penalty, if they meet together for the sole purpose of consulting upon and determining the rates of wages which those present at the meeting, or any of them, shall pay to their journeymen, workmen, or servants, for their work, or the hours of working, in any manufacture, trade, or business : neither shall they be liable to punishment for entering into any agreement, verbal or written, among them- selves, for the purpose of fixing the rate of TO TRADE UNIONS. 63 wages which the parties entering into the agreement, or any of them, shall pay to their journeymen, &c." In all the classes the elements of the crime, or offence, consist of an act and an intention. In each class, although the offence may be com mitted either by unionists or by non-unionists, yet the coercion or attempted coercion of the will of the party aggrieved is such as the trade unions, whether of employers or of working men, usually resort to in order to prevent the meeting of supply and demand, of labour and capital, in free competition. Accordingly, the operation of the statute is in practice applied almost entirely to alleged excesses on the part of trade unions. In the first class, relating to working men, the criminal intention must be to stop work, by pre- venting either the beginning or the continuance of an employment ; in the third class, relating to employers, the criminal intention must be either to force a change in the management of a business, or to check freedom in the em- ployment of labour ; in the second class, the criminal intention must be on behalf of some union to force either contribution to its funds or compliance with its rules. The terms de- scribing the intention, which is one element of the crime, are clear, and do not appear to have Chap. II. Stat'ites. §2. T/u- statute 6 Cro. 1 1 : C. i^q. 64 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. II Statutes. § 2. The Statute 6 Geo. IV. c. 129. Threats. led to much dispute, and may be passed without further notice ; but the terms describing the act, which is the other element of the crime, have caused doubt. The acts are described in terms of wide generality, in order that there may be com- prehended therein a wide class of actions which from their nature do not admit of precise defini- tion. The essence of the crime lies in the in- tention to coerce the will of another, indicated by some act comprised under one of the terms "violence," "threats," "intimidation," "molesta- tion," "obstruction;" and the act comprised within either of these terms is sufficient to con- stitute that element of the crime which lies in action if it was reasonably believed by the party committing it to be such as might coerce the will of the party to be affected thereby. Thus, as to the first term, an act of very slight assault, done for the purpose of assaulting, may be sufficient to prove violence within the mean- ing of the statute, when such slight assault was intended to be, and was probably, sufficient to coerce the will of a weak and timid person. So also of threats. If any person with the purpose of threatening conveys to the mind of another that he will bring any form of evil upon him, with the intent of forcing him to do one of the acts mentioned in the statute. TO TRADE UNIONS. 65 it seems to me that he has used a threat suf- ficient to constitute the guilt. The governing object of the statute is to secure the exercise of the free-will of each individual in disposing of his labour or his capital. It matters not what degree of evil may be suggested, if the sug- gestion is intended to take away free voluntary action as to the matters defined in the statute from the party to whom the suggestion is addressed. Evil may be inflicted in respect of the manifold interests relating to person, pro- perty, reputation, or affection. But I say no more on this point, because a material question has been raised — Whether a threat of bringing evil on a party, without otherwise violating any law in so doing, is a threat within the statute .-' I do not find an express adjudication on this point : as far as I can collect the opinions of the judges from incidental expressions, they appear to preponderate in favour of an answer in the negative. What has been said of the class of acts com- prised under the term " threat " is true in degree of intimidation. In each class the coercion is intended to be caused by fear : in threats the fear is caused by words ; in intimidation, by any deeds or words which might create fear. Wiiether the acts arc sufficient to prove intimi- dation within the statute ought to depend ui)on F Chap. II. Statutes. § 2. 77^1? Statuti' 6 Geo. IV. c. 129. Intimida- tion. ri6 THE LA IV RE LA T/NG Chap. II. Statutes. §2. The Statute 6 Ceo. IV. c. 129. yiotestation. < ibstrucfion the degree of timidity on the beHef of which the party intending to intimidate acted. So of acts of molestation. Any act which was intended to cause and did cause annoyance in a substantial degree to the party intended to be molested, if done with one of the prohibited intents, would constitute guilt within the meaning of this term. The measure of the degree of molestation is to be found in the sensibility of the sufferer, not in the act of the actor. B)' annoyance in a substantial degree, I mean the degree commonly referred to in actions for nuisances. The means of molestation vary in- finitely, considering all the channels through which annoyance may be sent to the human mind. Annoyances not sufficient to be an action- able nuisance to the residence, or an actionable damage to the reputation, if they were capable of molesting and were known to be so, and were done for the purpose of molesting with the prohibited intent, would be acts of moles- tation within the statute, according to my under- standing of it. And so of obstruction. Any act that ob- structs the exercise of any right, if done for the purpose of obstructing, and with the pro- hibited intent, would be sufficient. One fre- quent mode of committing this offence is by interfering with the right of passage on a high- TO TRADE UNIONS. 67 way. Every subject has the right to pass and re-pass at all times at his free-will and pleasure, this right being limited by the existence of a similar right in all other subjects ; and although the exercise of that similar right may operate as some obstruction to others, still it does not become unlawful thereby if done for the purpose of exercising the right, and if done in the degree reasonable for the exercise of that right. The right and the limitation are constantly exempli- fied in the uninterrupted passage of any crowd, either of passengers, or of animals, or of car- riages, where each uses the passage for himself with attention to the rights of passage for others. But if a person comes on a highway for any purpose other than that of passage, he is a trespasser ; and so the use of the highway for the purpose of shooting rabbits thereon was held to be a trespass (see R. v. Pratt, 4 Ell. & VA. 860). So, also, trespass lies for bringing cattle along a highway for the purpose of pas- ture, and not of passage. According to this doctrine, any use of the highway not for the purpose of lawful passage, but for the purpose of making passengers in any degree unwilling to pass to and from the premises of any party, with the intent of coercing the will of that party, and so of forcing him to do one of the acts specified in the statute, would be a criminal Chap. 11. Stauitcs. § 2. 7 he Statute eCeo. IV. c. I2g. 68 THE LA W RELA TING Chap. II. Statutes- § 2. Th,: Statute OGco.jy. (•■ 129. obstruction within the statute. Thus if a crowd were assembled in such numbers as to fill the street where the entrance to the premises was, and passed backwards and forwards so as to stop all access, with any other intent than that of using the right of passage, they would be guilty of an offence against the public by a criminal obstruction of the highway, and of an injury to the party to whose premises access was prevented, if he suffered special damage. They would also be guilty of an offence under the statute if they did so with intent to coerce the will of the party having any interest in such premises, and so to force him to one of the acts specified in the statute. These principles, and this interpretation of the statute, were enforced by Bramwell, B. in the cases of R. v. Druitt and R. V. Partridge (C. C. C. Aug. 21 and 22, 1867 ; 10 Cox C. C. 592), where the defendants had been concerned in the practice of picketing in the tailors' strike then pending. And that which is true of a crowd so assem- bled with the intent of causing an obstruction, and so of coercing the will as above described, is equally true of one person stationed as a watch to give Avarning, or the like, to persons passing to and fnjm the premises of the party whose I will is to be coerced, if he thereby obstructs I unhu\ full\- the cnjoA-mcnt of the rieht of free TO TRADE UNIONS. 69 passage for him and others, with intent to coerce his will and force him to one of the specified acts. The amount of actual obstruc- tion is no more material in this offence than the extent of actual removal of a chattel is material in larceny. The smallest wrongful act which is one of the series of acts by which the crime is to be completed externally, coupled with the criminal intention, is the misdemeanour of attempting to commit a crime. In burglary, the breaking may be by the lifting of a latch, and the entrance may be by inserting the tip of a finger. Ac- cording to this doctrine, the placing of pickets, as they are called, with the usual purpose of interfering with free passage by molesting, or the like, if done with one of the prohibited intents, is the crime of obstruction within the statute. It may also be at the same time the crime of molestation, or of threat, or of intimi- dation, within the statute ; it may also be a wrongful obstruction of the highway at common law, according to the circumstances ; and may be actionable and indictable. Chaf. 1 1 Statutes, § 2. riu- 'statute 6 Geo. n\ c. 129. I will further suggest that the words prohi- biting " molestation " and " obstruction," as well as violence, intimidation, and threats, are to be taken in their common acceptation, not limited by the words that precede. These THE LAW RELATING Chap. II. Statutes. ^ 2. The Statute 6 Ceo. IV. c. 129. two terms are additional to those in 5 Geo. IV. c. 95, and the Legislature must be taken to have added them with the intention that they should be so construed as to receive effect according to their ordinary acceptation. The description of the offences prohibited by the third section of 6 Geo. IV. c. 129 creates a difficulty in enforcing the statute, inasmuch as they are made to consist of an intentional act of grievance, with an ulterior intention to cause an act to be done by the party wronged. Thus, if an offence by molestation is taken as an example, there must be an act of molestation against the employer with intention to molest him — as by taking his men away — with an ulterior intention to force him to alter his mode of carrying on business — as by paying wages according to a book. Intention as an element of crime is more dif^cult of proof than acts of crime, and becomes more so in pro- portion as it is less closely connected with the act which is the other element of crime. The complications of statement required in indicting for a crime consisting of two intentions is seen in the twenty counts of the indictment for conspiracy to commit offences against this- statute in R. •:'. Rowlands (5 Cox C. C. 436). There is a further difficulty in applying the statute by reason that the description of the TO TRADE UNIONS. Cmak II. Statutes. §2. riu Statute 6 Geo. ll\ C. I2C,. classes of actions by the supposed wrong-doer, which are to constitute that element of the offence which lies in act, as contradistinguished from intention, consists more of the effect of that action upon another, than of the deed done by the wrong-doer himself. In respect of the first three classes — violence, threats, and intimi- dation — this remark is true to some extent, though practically acts of violence, threatening, or intimidation, can be recognised without diffi- culty. As to the remaining two classes — viz., molestation and obstruction — the description by which the guiltiness of the action imputed as the act of the offence can be tested, refers solely to the effect of the action either upon the feel- ings or upon the rights of the opposite party. The description, therefore, is wide enough to include every word or deed spoken or done for the purpose of molesting or obstructing, and producing the purposed effect, with one of the prohibited ulterior intents specified in the .statute. In respect of acts causing obstruc- tion, the difficulty is less than in the case of molestation. Nevertheless, the prohibition against molestation has vQvy important effects towards securing freedom from constraint. Sections 4 and 5,^ the substance of which has jf}„Jt/'b'^' been already given, are sections of permission, >rV''»"-f"'^ i See the text of these sections in Appendix B, p. 72 THE LAW RELA TING Chap. II. Statute.s. giving impunity to some combinations thereto- fore illegal. The principles of the common law have been above considered. The third section of the statute 6 Geo. IV. c. 1 29 enumerates certain violations of the right to free trade which are unlawful at common law as well as by this statute ; and in respect of these violations of free trade it enacts that there should be a summary remedy, as before explained ; then ss. 4 and 5 grant impunities in respect of the combinations therein mentioned, which are assumed to be illegal for restraint of trade, but which are exempted thereby from punishment. The fourth section exempts from any penal consequences as well meetings to consult on the wages which the persons present at the meeting shall accept, as any agreement respecting the wages which the persons entering into such agreement shall receive. Under this section unions can with impunity combine with respect to the wages and hours of the parties either present at the meeting or entering into the agreement. As the exemption is limited to parties present at a meeting, or entering into the agreement personally, it may be held that this power of combining for wages was intended to be confined to unions for a limited district, where the rate of wages, and the cost of TO TRADE UNIONS. 73 living, and other circumstances affecting a rate of wages, might be uniform, and was not intended to apply to extensive unions or amalgamations of unions. But it is a question of construction on which I find no adjudication.^ It gives to the workmen's unions within the ex- emption the power to combine for regulating the rate of the members' wages, but excludes them from interference in respect of the mode of carrying on business, or of the number of apprentices or journeymen, or of piecework, and other trade matters ; and by s. 5 the same pro- visions, mutatis nuitandis, are applied to masters. It should be borne in mind that the impunity is limited to combinations for the purpose of directly raising or lowering wages, as described in the section, and does not extend to combi- nations immediately for crimes and mediately through those crimes for a rise of wages. Com- binations to exclude apprentices, piecework, and overtime are indirectly to increase wages, but the words of exemption do not in my opinion extend to such combinations. As the unions, although coming within the exemption from punishment, remain unlawful if they operate in unlawful restraint of trade, 1 Since this was written the Amalgamated Society of Cai- penters has been held to be legal, no objection being taken on the ground of amalgamation. (Faner v. Close, Q. B., Jan. i8, 1868.) Chap. II. Statute.-. §2. The Statute 6Gi-/>. /r. C. I2!hy v. Close. 7« THE LA W RELA TING Chap. 11 Statutes §4. The Statute 18 &= 19 I'ict. c. 63, s. 44. event, on the happening of which the jurisdic- tion is to attach, should be defined. Tliis lias been clearly done in respect of friendly societies, but in respect of trade unions the operative words are, that a society " established for an)' purpose which is not illegal " may claim aid from the summary jurisdiction. Then arises the ques- tion — What is a "society" within the meaning of this section 1 The term is wide enough to include trade unions, but it also includes ever}' concert of two or more to act together, and therefore includes more than can have been intended. If the excess is to be limited to societies cjusdcni generis with friendly societies, the rule is grievously vague. But assuming that a trade union may be a .-.ociety within the Act, if it is not for an illegal purpose, what are the " purposes" of a society 1 As a society it has no mind, and the beginning of its action must be by resolution of the whole or the governing part of the members ; and if the purposes are only those which are declared by resolution, the provision against illegal purposes is almost nullified, as they might not be declared. But whether the purposes are those expressed in resolutions, or secretly entertained, how is the magistrate to ascertain their existence ? And I I yet he must do so at his peril before he exercises I the juiisdiction, unless it should be held that the TO TRADE UNIONS. 79 purposes are presumed to be legal till that pre- sumption be rebutted by evidence. In the case of Hornby v. Close, these difficulties as to as- certaining the purposes of the society were re- moved, because the rules were produced, and were held to operate in restraint of trade, inas- much as they prohibited piecework under pain of fine and expulsion. The effect of this case has been misunderstood if it is supposed to decide that the members of trade unions have not all the ordinary remedies for violations of rights of property which the members of the community in general possess. They have difficulties from the shifting of mem- bers, and from joint ownership, as explained above ; but they may proceed by action or in- dictment where other subjects would have a right to do so, and in those proceedings the legality or illegality of their purposes is immaterial. They might have also the benefits of incorporation, and therewith all the powers of the law to en- force their rules, and protect their rights, if they would take the law to be as it is laid down by the competent tribunals, and alter their rules conformably thereto. Ch/M'. II Statutes. §4. The Statute 18 &f 19 Vict. c. 63, J. 44. Since the above was written, it has been de- cided in Farrer v. Close (O.B. Januar}- 18, 1868), Fe>- V. Close. TRADES UNIONS. Ch.m-. II. Statutes. 5 4- The Statute iS &y' 19 \ ict c. 63. s. 44. that the Amalgamated Society of Carpenters was entitled to the benefit of the 44th section of the Friendly Societies' Act, against an officer who had misappropriated the money of the society. The rules authorized the application of the funds to various trade purposes, and among others to the support of members when out of work ; and although it was objected that the funds might thus be applied to maintain strikes, it was said that a strike was not necessarily illegal ; and the case was distinguished from Hornby i\ Close, because there was no rule operating directly in restraint of trade, such as the rule prohibiting piecework in the latter case. The inferences from the judgment in Farrer v. Close seem important for the interests of trade unions, as regards both the recognition of the legality of some strikes, and the indication of the boundary between legal and illegal purposes within the meaninsf of this section. APPENDIX A. Some Account of the Trials of R. v. Rowlands AND Others, and R. v. Duffield and Others (S Cox C. C. 436 AND 404). * On the trial of these cases the judge said certain' am'kmh.v things to the jury which have since been cited as if he J^_ laid down propositions of law absolutely. But in all ; R. v. Row- cases it is essential for the correct understanding of j r'! Duffilw. " the words of a judge to bear in mind the facts to I which they relate. The account of the trial may be of use in showing 1 the meaning of the ruling, and in exemplifying the importance of security under the law for the disposing of labour as well as capital. I describe the facts according to the effect of the evidence on my mind. In 1849, i'^ Wolverhampton, there were six firms of tin-plate workers and japan- ners, who made and japanned tin-plate articles. With- out understanding the manufacture, I assume for the purpose of this case that some of these articles could be made by hand with three processes, viz. punching holes, cutting out pieces, and joining the pieces; and that some of these firms possessed machinery for some of these processes, Messrs. Perry making more use of machinery than their rivals. The workmen in , Wolverhampton were usually paid by the article, so much for a cullender or a pepper-box. Some of the Wolverhampton unions had proposed a book of prices, \ APPENDIX. Ali'KNDIX A. K. V. K..«-- lands and R. :•. Diiffield. which were to be uniform for each article ; but as the proper wages for workmen who did all processes by hand, if paid on this principle, would be too much for workmen who did some processes only by hand and some by machinery, and as the wages claimed were not supposed to be properly adjusted according to the use of machinery, the two firms of the Messrs. Perry did not consent to pay according to the pro- posed book of prices ; but they paid such prices that their workmen received for their time more than work- men for other firms who were paid according to the book. The Messrs. Perry prospered, and their workmen were well off and contented ; but as they undersold the rival manufacturers, and as they superseded hand- labour by machinery, there were two sources of hostility towards them. In November 1849, Messrs. Perr)' and Son, one of the firms, saw reason to be dissatisfied with a work- man named Preston, and discharged him. There was a National Association of United Trades in London, of which the defendant Peel was secretary, the defendant Green a delegate, and the defendant Winters a member. The other defendants were mem- bers of provincial unions ; but not one of them was employed by Messrs. Perry, or had any monied in- terest at stake in the strike, as far as I could perceive. The reserve fund of the National Association was stated to be more than 20,000/., and Preston, it was said, had contributed and procured contributions thereto. Preston seems to have applied to this asso- ciation in respect of his discharge by his employers. The following is the account by Mr. George Henry Perry of the setting in of the strike : — APPENDIX. " I am a manufacturer at Wolverhampton, canying | Adendix A. on business under the firm of Perry and Son. I have carried it on for twenty years, and my father did before I ^^^ me. In the spring of 1S50 I had 120 men, half for tin work, half for japan. The japan workers depend on the tin workers. During the first three months of 1850 we were in good work with large orders. The workmen's wages would range from 25^-. to 5 ox., but some earned 60^. In November 1849 I discharged Thomas Preston. I was not aware of any differences between me and my workmen in the spring of 1850. We had been comfortable for many years before we received a certain letter. "In the second week of December, 1849, Green called about Preston. He stated he was a member of the National Association of United Trades, of which Thomas Duncombe, M.P. was president, that they had considerable funds (20,000/. I believe) at the .delegates' command, and that nearly the entire work- ing population was co-operating with them. I said, 'Mr. Green, what is your business with me?' He replied, ' You've discharged Thomas Preston ; ['ve called to know the reason.' I said we did not require Preston's services, that was our reason for discharging him. He asked if it was not because he belonged to the club that we discharged him. (The club is the Tin-plate Workers' Society.) I said the reason we dis- charged him was because we did not want his services. He again asked if it was not because he belonged to the club ; if it was, they should take all the men out ; they should stop the supplies, so that not a man should call. He then left me with the assurance from me that we discharged Preston because we did not want Row- lands and K. V. DuffielJ. 84 APPENDIX. AM'ENDIX A. R. V. Row- lands and R. V. Duffield. his services. The question I put was this, that he had better mind his own business, and not come meddUng and interfering with ours. He did not mention any name then. Nothing else jjassed that I recollect. " I received a letter about the 3d of April, which was dated 2d April, 1850, headed 'Selling-book of prices,' and signed " ' Fredk. Green, | Mediators, not in an " ' Thos. Winters, i offensive spirit^ [The letter was produced and read.] " After I had received this letter Green called about the 1 2th April. He said he was a delegate from the National Association, and he and Mr. Peel had come down to settle the difference between us and our workmen. I told him that I was not aware there was any difference between us and our men, and that if our men had anything to complain of, and would come to me, we could settle it without his interference ; and begged that he would not come meddling with our business. He then said he wished us to adopt a book of prices which the men had written out, and of which a copy had been sent us. I said I had not had an opportunity of looking at the list, but I would do so in a few days of leisure. Nothing else occurred. " He called again in a week or fortnight. He again urged me to adopt this book of prices, and said if we did not they should take all the men out. As we had very large orders for America unexecuted, I did not tell him pointedly we would not pay the book, but that we would consider of it, so as to get time and to get some more men hired. I did not wish to have the men taken out. Nothing else occurred." The sequel of the evidence describes the course of APPENDIX. 85 the strike. If I rightly appreciate it, it shows the power of evil in remorseless activity, destroying those relations between employers and employed on which comfort and peace depend, bringing guilt and misery on the workmen and ruin on their employers. The Messrs. Perry maintained their right for freedom for the course of labour with energy. Hoping for support according to law, they tried all the resources for labour in England. They tried to go on with apprentices and boys, and twice imported a band of artisans from France. But in vain ; their factories were deserted, and their trade stopped. The workmen were induced, some to break their contracts, others to leave their employ without notice. Pickets at every approach were busy with all that came and went ; money was paid largely to get work- men away — 600/. for the removal of the Frenchmen alone. Some of the men were supplied with liquor and induced to go to the railway station, and to enter a carriage without knowing the purpose. They were conveyed to different places, where a scanty supply of money was sent for a few weeks, and then many were left to themselves ; their discomfort may be imagined from the case of two workmen who, being left penniless, walked home fifty-two miles without a farthing to sup- port them, and were so blamed for returning that the wife of one of them had to stop the coarse abuse upon her husband by threatening to use a brush handle to drive them out of the house. But the guilt towards the apprentices was worse ; not only were they taught to disregard their contracts and to abscond, but one of the defendants was stated to have made a suggestion " that apprentices could do Appendix A R. V. Row- lands and R. z'. Duffield. 86 APPENDIX. Appendix A. R. V. Row- lands and R. 'J. Duffield. them great service if they would ; he remembered when he was connected with leather what game the apprentices played in cutting up and destroying leather ; and the foreman of Messrs. Perry deposed that before the apprentices went away the tools were injured, the tin was cut to waste, and the patterns were missing. After the close of the strike a party of apprentices were said to have been found huddled in a garret in London. This misery was inflicted by parties, many of whom seemed ill qualified to appreciate the importance ot the matter in dispute. Judging from outward appear- ances, the London defendants were men of high respectability, with intellect and experience qualifying them to discern at a glance the essence of any trans- action they were engaged in, and to guide the course of it \ the provincial defendants seemed to be little more than instalments in their hands. It was not clear that there was any monied interest at stake ; some of the witnesses said that wages according to the book would be lower than the current rate with- out the book. It is not probable that the president of the association understood or cared for useful industry, or that their secretary or delegate understood about the book of prices, if the description of the question respecting the book was correctly given by Mr. Perry. But it may be that the dragging of two well-established firms of manufacturers down from a station of wealth and influence through various stages to ruin would be an impressive warning not to trust to the law for help against a trade union ; it may be that there was a probability of increased subscriptions if a master was sacrificed for discharging a servant ; it may also be that the defendants believed they were promoting the APPENDIX. 87 interest of working men. Motives are never matter of certain knowledge. According' as the motives should be found honest or corrupt so would the liability be, if the principles here stated are correct. It was at the close of the trial that the judge used some of the words which have been brought into question, first informing the jury, in effect, that they were not trying workmen for combining to obtain a rise of their own wages, and then stating that they were trying the defendants for other and different offences, as set forth in the indictment ; and, among other things, ruling that there was evidence to go to the jury against Winters and Rowlands, although the only overt acts of conspiracy in evidence against them were acts of persuading men while the strike was going on to leave Messrs. Perry's employ, without using threats or intimidation. The case of R. v. Rowlands is in substance the same as R. v. Dufifield ; in the one the defendants struck against Messrs. Perry and Son, in the other they struck against the finn of Mr. Edward Perry. The question of the book was the ground of the strike against both firms, and both firms rejected the book for the reason above explained. The facts of this case, taken with the reasoning of the foregoing Memorandum, raise two questions : first. Did every member of the executive committee in London, who authorised Messrs. Green and Peel to take part in the strike, incur the same criminal guilt as Messrs. Green and Peel ? and secondly, Was every such member of that committee liable in an action by every person who suffered damage from that strike, and was every such person entitled to recover therein the amount of such damage? ArPENDIX A. R. V. Row- lands and R. V. Duffield. APPENDIX B. Sections 3, 4, 5, of the Act 6 Geo. IV. c. 129. Appendix B. 6 Geo. IV. [ c. lag, ss. 3, 4.5- Penalty on Persons compellhig your?ieyiuen to leave their Employ- ment, or to return lVo)-A- unjinislied ; or prevent- ing their Hiring tlumselves ; or compell- ing them to belong to Clubs, &'c. ; or to pay any Fines, for not having III. And be it further enacted, That from and after the passing of this Act, if any Person shall by Violence to the Person or Property, or by Threats or Intimidation, or by molesting or in any way obstruct- ing another, force or endeavour to force any Journey- man, Manufacturer, Workman, or other Person hired or employed in any Manufacture, Trade, or Business, to depart from his Hiring, Employment, or Work, or to return his Work before the same shall be finished, or prevent or endeavour to prevent any Journeyman, Manufacturer, Workman, or other Person not being hired or employed from hiring himself to, or from accepting Work or Employment from any Person or Persons ; or if any Person shall use or employ Violence to the Person or Property of another, or Threats or Intimidation, or shall molest or in any way obstruct ano;her for the Purpose of forcing or in- ducing such Person to belong to any Club or Association, or to contribute to any common Fund, or to pay any Fine or Penalty, or on account of his not belonging to any particular Club or Association, or not having contributed or having refused to contribute to any common Fund, or to pay any Fine or Penalty, or on account of his not having complied or of his refusing to comply with any APPENDIX. 89 Rules, Orders, Resolutions, or Regulations made to obtain an Advance or to reduce the Rate of Wages, or to lessen or alter the Hours of Working, or to decrease or alter the Quantity of Work, or to regulate the Mode of carrying on any Manufacture, Trade, or Business, or the Management thereof; or if any Person shall by Violence to the Person or Property of another, or by Threats or Intimidation, or by molest- ing or in any way obstructing another, force or endeavour to force any Manufacturer or Person carry- ing on any Trade or Business, to make any Alteration in his Mode of regulating, managing, conducting, or carrying on such Manufacture, Trade, or Business, or to limit the Number of his Apprentices, or the Number or Description of his Journeymen, Workmen, or Servants ; every Person so offending, or aiding, abet- ting, or assisting therein, being convicted thereof in Manner herein after mentioned, shall be imprisoned only, or shall and may be imprisoned and kept to Hard Labour, for any Time not exceeding Three Calendar Months. IV. Provided always, and be it enacted, That this Act shall not extend to subject any Persons to Punish- ment who shall meet together for the sole Purpose of consulting upon and determining the Rate of Wages or Prices, which the Persons present at such Meeting or any of them, shall require or demand for his or their Work, or the Hours or Time for which he or they shall work in any Manufacture, Trade, or Business, or who shall enter into any Agreement, verbal or Wi-itten, among themselves, for the Purpose of fixing the Rate of Wages of Prices which the Parties enter- ing into such Agreement, or any of them, shall re- H Appendix B. 6 Geo. IV. c. 129, ss. 3, 4.5- cotnplied with Orders as to Wages ; or compell- ing any Manufac- turer, dr'c. to alter his viode of carrying on Business ; hnprison- nient, or Imprison- ment with Hard Labour for Three Months. Not to affect Meetiiigsfor settling Kates of IV ages to be 7-eccived, or Hours of Work to be employed by the Persons tneeting. 90 APPENDIX. Appendix B. 6 Geo. IV. c. 129, ss. 3, 4. 5- Not to affect Meetings for Rates 0/ Wages, &^c. to be paid by Masters to yourney- men, i^c. quire or demand for his or their work, or the Hours of Time for which he or they will work, in any Manu- facture, Trade, or Business ; and that Persons so meeting for the Purposes aforesaid, or entering into any such Agreement as aforesaid, shall not be liable to any Prosecution or Penalty for so doing ; any Law or Statute to the contrary notwithstanding. V. Provided also, and be it further enacted. That this Act shall not extend to subject any Persons to Punishment who shall meet together for the sole Pur- pose of consulting upon and determining the Rate of Wages or Prices which the Persons present at such Meeting, or any of them, shall pay to his or their Journeyman, Workmen, or Servants, for their Work, or the Hours or Time of working in any Manufac- ture, Trade, or Business, or who shall enter into any Agreement, verbal or written, among themselves, for the Purpose of fixing the Rate of Wages or Prices, which the Parties entering into such Agreement, or any of them, shall pay to his or their Journeymen, Workmen, or Servants, for their Work, or the Hours or Time of working in any Manufacture, Trade, or Business ; and that Persons so meeting for the Pur- poses aforesaid, or entering into any such Agreement as aforesaid, shall not be liable to any Prosecution or Penalty for so doing, any Law or Statute to the con- trary notwithstanding. Section 44 of the Act 18 & 19 Vict. c. 63. 18 & 19 Vict. I XLIV. In ihe case of any Friendly Society estab- c. 03, s. 44' J, g, f~ lished for any of the Purposes mentioned in Section o/socUties IX. of this Act, or for any Purpose which is not APPENDIX. 91 illegal, having written or printed Rules, whose Rules have not been certified by the Registrar, provided a Copy of such Rules shall have been deposited with the Registrar, every Dispute between any Member or Members of such Society, and the Trustees, Trea- surer, or other Officer, or the Committee of such Society, shall be decided in manner herein-before provided with respect to Disputes, and the Decision thereof, in the Case of Societies to be established under this Act, and the Sections in this Act provided for such Decision and also the Section in this Act which enacts a Punishment in case of Fraud or Imposition by an Officer, Member, or Person, shall be applicable to such uncertified Societies : Provided always, that nothing herein contained shall be con- strued to confer on any such Society whose Rules shall not have been certified by the Registrar, or any of the Members or Officers of such Society, any of the Powers, Exemptions, or Facilities of this Act, save and except as in and by this Section is expressly provided. Appendix B. 18 & 19 Vict, c. 63, s. 44. ivhose Rules are not cer- tified^ Dis- putes be- tiveen tlie Society and its own Members to be settled as in Cases of certified Societies. Section i of the Act 22 Vict. c. 34. I. That no Workman or other Person, whether 2^vict. c. 34, S. I. actually in Employment or not, shall, by reason merely of his entering into an Agreement Avith any Workman or Workmen, or other Person or Persons, for the pur- pose of fixing or endeavouring to fix the Rate of Wages or Remuneration at which they or any of them shall work, or by reason merely of his endeavouring peaceably, and in a reasonable Manner, and without Threat or Intimidation, direct or indirect, to persuade Agreenients in certain Cases not to be deemed "Molesta- tion " or " Obstruc- tion," APPENDIX. Appendix others to ccasc Or abstain from Work in order to obtain the Rate of Wages or the altered Hours of "Vict. c. 34, Labour so fixed ot agreed upon or to be agreed upon, shall be deemed or taken to be guilty of " Molesta- tion" or " Obstruction," within the Meaning of the said Act, and shall not therefore be subject or liable to any Prosecution or Indictment for Conspiracy : Provided always, that nothing herein contained shall authorize any Workman to break or depart from any Contract or authorize any Attempt to induce any Workman to break or depart from any Contract. •within the Meaning of the recited Act. London: r. clav, s.)ns, and tavi.oi;, im<:\ters. CO A\\EUNIVEW//, o o %a3AiNn3i\v 4^? ^ "^AdMiNrta^v^ aofcaufo% > ^OFCALlFOft^ .^WEUNIVERS/A ^lOSANCEUf^ o ^ "^^smmi^ v^lOSANCEl^^ O 3 ^•UBRARYQr 4^^UBRARYQr^ ^•OFCAllFOfti^ ^OFCAllFOftjk ^IUBRARYQa ^;J^l•UBRARY(9/, ^\WEUMIVER% ^lOSANCElfj-^ ^AOJIIVDJO-^ '^ '-rrr" i c?. > V/ _ Ig g £2 =s >- ex: ^WM ^ =3 :AllFOMi^ In*! ^lUBRAfiYOc ^OFCAIIFO%, UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY AA 000 825 350 2 ^J:?U3NYS01^ ,\WEUUIVER% ''3a;lAlf IKIVfKi//, DNVSOl^^ ■^^/5aaAiNn-3\\v ^sSlUBRARY^^ ^l-UBRARY6)/, ^- mms//^ ^viosANCEifj> ^iHAINfli^V" ^•OFCALIFOff^ ^.OFCAllFOft)^ ^ ^^'^ >&Aiivaan-^^ c^-' BRARY^k^ inv3J0>' 5^lUBHARYa<;^ ^immus//^ ^iosANcn% hoim-i^'^