fW.Y~'3<S. . : , ;i,'"' 
 
 ' - 
 
 THE RISE.B
 
 THE LIBRARY 
 
 OF 
 
 THE UNIVERSITY 
 OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 LOS ANGELES
 
 To be published monthly. 
 
 The 
 
 Victorian Era Series. 
 
 In crown 8vo volumes, cloth boards, 2s. 6d. each. 
 
 The series is designed to form a record of the 
 great movements and developments of the age, 
 in politics, economics, religion, industry, literature, 
 science, and art, and of the life work of its typical 
 and influential men. 
 
 Under the general editorship of Mr. J. HOLLAND 
 ROSE, M.A., late Scholar of Christ's College, Cam- 
 bridge, the individual volumes will be contributed 
 by leading specialists in the various branches of 
 knowledge which fall to be treated in the series. 
 
 On i^th November. 
 
 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 By J. HOLLAND ROSE, M.A., late Scholar of Christ's College, 
 Cambridge (Editor of the Series). 
 
 On i^th December. 
 
 The Anglican Revival. 
 
 By J. H. OVERTON, D.D., Rector of Epworth and Canon of 
 Lincoln. 
 
 In preparation 
 
 Charles Kingsley. 
 
 By the Very Rev. C. W. STUBBS, D.D., Dean of Ely. 
 
 [OVER.
 
 The Growth and Administration of the British 
 
 Colonies, 1837-1897. 
 By the Rev. W. GRESWELL, M.A. 
 
 The Free Trade Movement and its Results. 
 
 By G. ARMITAGE SMITH, Principal of the Birbeck Institution, 
 and for many years Lecturer on Economics for the London 
 Society for the Extension of University Teaching. 
 
 John Bright. 
 
 By C. A. VINCE, M.A., late Fellow of Christ's College, Cam- 
 bridge. 
 
 The Growth of London, 1837-1897. 
 By G. LAURENCE GOMME. 
 
 Charles Dickens. 
 
 By GEORGE GISSING. 
 
 National Education. 
 
 By H. HOLMAN, M.A., one of H.M. Inspectors of Schools. 
 
 Recent Advances in Astronomy. 
 
 By A. H. FISON, D.Sc. 
 
 The Science of Life. 
 
 By J. ARTHUR THOMSON, M.A. 
 
 Indian Life and Thought since the Mutiny. 
 
 By R. P. KARKARIA, B.A. 
 
 * Further announcements will be made from time to time. 
 
 BLACKIE & SON, LIMITED, 
 LONDON. GLASGOW, AND DUBLIN.
 
 \Dictorfan J6ra Series 
 
 The Rise of Democracy
 
 The Rise 
 
 of 
 
 Democracy 
 
 By 
 
 J. HOLLAND ROSE, M.A. 
 
 Late Scholar of Christ's College, Cambridge; author of 
 "The Revolutionary and Napoleonic Era" 
 
 LONDON 
 
 BLACKIE & SON, LIMITED, 50 OLD BAILEY, E.G. 
 
 GLASGOW AND DUBLIN 
 
 1897
 
 sso 
 
 General Preface. 
 
 As the present volume is introductory to the Victorian Era 
 Series, it is proper to explain the purport of the series as a 
 whole. It aims at describing in attractive and scholarly form 
 the chief movements of our age and the lifework of its influential 
 men. Each volume will deal with a well-defined subject, which 
 it will exhibit in its historical setting and in its relation to 
 present conditions. Collaboration, recognized as being an 
 essential of modern historical work, has been adopted in this 
 series, in that each volume will be the work of a writer who has 
 made its subject a special study. This will, it is hoped, ensure 
 the coherence of the individual volumes, and the unity and 
 balance of the series as a whole. 
 
 In this volume I have endeavoured to describe, as fully as 
 limits of space permit, the course of the political movement 
 which has profoundly modified the whole of our public life. 
 One remark as to the usage of terms seems to be called for here 
 Throughout my inquiry I have used the term democracy in its 
 strict sense, as government by the people, and not in the slipshod 
 way in which it is now too often employed to denote the wage- 
 earning classes. That this misuse of the term is responsible for 
 much slipshod thought on political matters, will, I trust, be made 
 clear in the latter part of this little work. 
 
 The Radical movement attained strength and persistence in 
 the first years of Queen Victoria's reign; and its peaceful char- 
 acter has been due in no small degree to the loyalty awakened 
 by the Queen's personal character and life. But in order to 
 understand the aims of the Radicals who drew up the Charter, 
 it is necessary to review the trend of events during the preceding 
 generation, and to connect the political history of the present 
 reign with the social and economic problems which became an 
 urgent part of practical politics on the conclusion of the great 
 war. After tracing the origin and general course of the Chartist 
 movement, I have endeavoured to show its connection with the 
 latter-day Radicalism, which led up to the Reform Acts of 1867 
 
 1368021
 
 vi General Preface. 
 
 and 1884-85; and in the two closing chapters I have ven- 
 tured on a brief examination of two of the burning questions 
 of the day. In regard to these topics Labour Legislation 
 and Foreign Policy I have striven calmly to look facts in the 
 face, and to inquire by the light of the teachings of the past, what 
 is the significance of the present situation. In one respect, the 
 present time seems opportune for some such inquiry as is hazarded 
 in this little work. The lull in the strife of political parties 
 affords a good opportunity for a quiet consideration of our 
 actual position and a deliberate survey of the course of the 
 struggle. That there has been a striking change in the relations 
 of parties and the conduct of the fight will be evident to all 
 who contrast the political speeches of to-day with the excited 
 harangues of 1880-5; while those again will seem tame beside 
 the fervid declamations of the " forties ". 
 
 In my treatment of the more strictly historical parts of the 
 subject, I have purposely given only the briefest reference to 
 many politicians who figure largely in Parliamentary annals or 
 in the gossip of Pall Mall. My desire has been rather to dwell 
 on the efforts of humbler individuals, who stirred up the artisans 
 of England to action which finally compelled responsible states- 
 men to listen to their demands. I have accordingly bestowed 
 more attention on William Cobbett than on Viscount Melbourne, 
 on Henry Vincent than on Lord John Russell. In some direc- 
 tions this little work essays to open up new ground, and where 
 I have described well-known events I have endeavoured to 
 invest them with a new significance by approaching them from 
 the point of view of the workman's club rather than of the lobby 
 of St. Stephen's. In relation to Free-trade, Irish affairs, educa- 
 tional efforts, and the work of several influential thinkers and 
 statesmen, my narrative may seem incomplete ; but these topics 
 will be handled in other volumes of the series. 
 
 My indebtedness to other workers in this field is, I believe, 
 everywhere acknowledged in foot-notes. For valuable advice 
 on several topics I must express my grateful acknowledgments 
 to Mr. G. Laurence Gomme, and to Messrs. C. V. Coates and 
 G. W. Johnson, both of Trinity College, Cambridge. 
 
 J. H. ROSE. 
 BALHAM, S.W., October^' *897-
 
 Contents. 
 
 CHAPTER I 
 
 Page 
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism 9 
 
 CHAPTER II 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832 - - - - 3 2 
 
 CHAPTER III 
 The Revolt against the New Poor Laws - 52 
 
 CHAPTER IV 
 The Fight for a Free Press 62 
 
 CHAPTER V 
 Crown, Parliament, and People (1837) - - 77 
 
 CHAPTER VI 
 The Rise of 'Chartism (1838-1839) - 84 
 
 CHAPTER VII 
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists - - - 97 
 
 CHAPTER VIII 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement - 114 
 
 CHAPTER IX 
 Revolution or Evolution f I2 $
 
 viii Contents. 
 
 CHAPTER X 
 
 Pag* 
 
 Phases of Political Thought ..... jfj 
 
 ^^_____ CHAPTER XI 
 ^The Reform Bills of 1866-1867^ " - - - 167 
 
 CHAPTER XII 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion - - - - 186 
 
 ^ CHAPTER XIII 
 
 \The Third Reform Act 200 
 
 CHAPTER XIV 
 Democracy and Labour - 214. 
 
 CHAPTER XV 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy ----- 235 
 
 INDEX 249
 
 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Chapter I. 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 
 
 Any inquiry into the course of democratic progress in 
 England would be confessedly flimsy and superficial 
 which did not endeavour, however briefly, to indicate 
 the nature of the movement in its earlier stages. Is 
 English democracy of home growth, or does it owe its 
 chief impulse to the cognate movement in France? Was 
 it propelled onwards by a conscious striving after new 
 ideals, or was it merely the result of discontent aroused 
 by material discomforts and unjust laws? Did our 
 Radical reformers claim that they were initiating a new 
 era for humanity at large, or were they content with 
 redressing the ills of the time? To these and similar 
 questions it is hoped that this little work will furnish 
 some reply, not, as a rule, explicitly and in set terms, 
 but rather by means of an unbiassed narrative which 
 will leave the reader free to draw his own conclusions 
 as to the drift of events, the full significance of which 
 cannot as yet be fully realized. 
 
 A few words may not be out of place here to suggest 
 one important difference which separates the democracy 
 of the last hundred years from that of the ancient world. 
 Popular government, as we now know it, aims at con- 
 ceding full political rights and duties to all adult males 
 who are not obviously disqualified properly to discharge
 
 io The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 them. We should now deny the name of democrat to 
 any who would withhold these rights from a majority 
 of the adult men of the state. In the ancient worla, on 
 the other hand, popular government never contemplated, 
 even as a possible contingency, that civic responsibility 
 should ever be accorded to the slaves, on whom fell 
 nearly all the burdens of menial employments. Govern- 
 ment was therefore in the hands of a minority, sometimes 
 of a small minority. Oftener still it was the tool of a 
 faction; but there is no instance of a defeated faction 
 deliberately enfranchising the hewers of wood and 
 drawers of water in order to compass the overthrow of 
 its successful rivals. Such a proposal would have been 
 wholly unintelligible to the democrats of ancient Greece 
 and Rome. 1 
 
 The political and social problems which modern de- 
 mocracy has endeavoured to solve are therefore im- 
 measurably wider and grander than any which came 
 within the ken of the philosophers and statesmen of the 
 ancient world. To what influence are we to attribute 
 the broadening and humanizing tendencies of modern 
 politics? Primarily to the love of individual liberty 
 cherished by the Teutonic tribes who laid the founda- 
 tions of a new social order throughout Western Europe. 
 Their sense of the dignity of man as man, when 
 strengthened by Christian teaching, opened up a new 
 future, which was to receive its fullest and most un- 
 fettered development in England. It was here that re- 
 presentative government found its first complete expres- 
 sion in a national Parliament as the guardian of popular 
 liberties a fact which decisively answers the question 
 as to the native origin of our democracy in its early or 
 mediaeval phase. But the question as to the origin of 
 the great impulse towards popular government charac- 
 
 1 Cf. Aristotle's Nic. Ethics, bk. x. chap. 6: "No one allows a slave to 
 share in happiness any more than in the life of a citizen ".
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. n 
 
 teristic of the last century scarcely admits of so clear an 
 answer; for under the warping" influence of time, intrigue, 
 and war, the essentially democratic features of our earlier 
 parliamentary system were gradually effaced, until there 
 seemed to be some danger that the masterful influence 
 of George III., and the bribes skilfully administered by 
 the "King's Friends", would degrade the constitution of 
 the United Kingdom to the level of that of the Electorate 
 of Hanover. 
 
 It was at this crisis of our history, when our affairs 
 seemed about "to be hurried into the rage of civil 
 violence or to sink into the dead repose of despotism ", 
 that a great thinker, renowned not less for his conser- 
 vatism than his candour, reawakened the flame of 
 patriotic enthusiasm for our ancient constitutional 
 liberties. In his Thoughts upon the Present Discontents 
 (1770) Burke complained that the House of Commons 
 was beginning to exercise control upon the people, 
 whereas " it was designed as a control for the people". 
 Lifting up his voice in protest against the insidious 
 influence of the secret Cabal, which intrigued in the 
 supposed interests of the king, he called on the people 
 to defeat its aims by compelling public men to pay 
 attention first and foremost to public opinion, so that 
 the House of Commons might again become, what it 
 ought to be, "the express image of the feelings of the 
 nation ". To this end the whole body of the people 
 must be called in to watch the proceedings of Parlia- 
 ment, must distribute lists of the votes given by mem- 
 bers, and by the pressure of public opinion must seek to 
 diminish the subservience of the House of Commons to 
 the crown. Not that Burke was republican: far from 
 it. His aim all through his political career was to re- 
 store and then to maintain that balance of powers be- 
 tween crown, Lords, and Commons which he regarded 
 as the essential feature of the English constitution.
 
 12 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 An interesting result of his protest, and of the excite- 
 ment arising out of the prosecutions of Wilkes, was soon 
 to be seen. In 1780 a band of energetic reformers, 
 among whom Major Cartwright and Home Tooke were 
 the most prominent, founded the Society for Constitu- 
 tional Information, which published several pamphlets 
 to prove the urgent need of parliamentary reform. At a 
 meeting of the society presided over by the great Whig 
 orator, Charles James Fox, a programme, which was 
 destined to be revived fifty-eight years later by the Char- 
 tists, was adopted as summarizing the aims of zealous 
 Whig reformers. It comprised the following as its most 
 prominent demands annual parliaments, universal suf- 
 frage, equal voting districts, abolition of the property 
 qualification for members of Parliament, payment of 
 members, and vote by ballot at parliamentary elec- 
 tions. Only by the attainment of these reforms, so the 
 society affirmed, could the House of Commons regain 
 its old position as the guardian of the people's liberties 
 against all encroachments by the other estates of the 
 realm. 
 
 But, apart from their historical significance, these 
 proceedings of the first important reform club were with- 
 out any immediate result. Parliament and people alike 
 yawned at the mere mention of reform; and after seem- 
 ingly fruitless efforts at educating public opinion, the 
 society decently expired. Its work, however, was not to 
 perish. The exposure of the abuses of court patronage, 
 and of the sordid obsequiousness of a Parliament of 
 borough-mongers, was soon to arouse a storm of indig- 
 nation when the lightning flashes of the French Revolu- 
 tion of 1789 lit up the darkness of the night. At once 
 the old apathy to matters political disappeared as if by 
 magic. Scores of clubs were founded on the model of the 
 famous Jacobin Club of Paris, and several of them es- 
 sayed to imitate the trenchant vigour of the attacks of
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 13 
 
 Robespierre's disciples on old institutions. Certainly the 
 Gothic irregularities of the English political edifice fa- 
 voured the attacks of the "radical reformers" a name 
 now first used in the heated controversies of the time to 
 denote those who would tolerate no mere patchwork, 
 but demanded a reconstruction of the old edifice on an 
 essentially popular basis. The Birmingham Club dis- 
 tinguished itself by a vigorous attack on the abuses and 
 absurdities of our electoral system, declaring in its 
 manifesto that the constitution was a venerable fraud, 
 and that seats for the House of Commons were sold as 
 openly as stalls for cattle at a fair. The same facts, 
 when set forth in more academic language by reformers 
 in 1780, had evoked no general response. Yet, in 1792, 
 English public opinion seemed about to become scarcely 
 less Jacobinical than that of France. In both lands the 
 extreme reformers were in a small minority; but the 
 decision of their views and the weakness of the systems 
 which they attacked seemed to promise a speedy triumph 
 to democracy of the most advanced type. But the im- 
 pulse which came from France, though potent, was 
 transient. The diversion of her democratic ardour into 
 the alluring vistas of military glory, opened up by Bona- 
 parte, soon alienated her warmest admirers on these 
 shores ; and the wave of French political influence ebbed 
 almost as rapidly as it had flowed over our land. In 
 Parliament its effect had been even directly unfavourable 
 to the cause which Home Tooke and Cartwright had 
 championed. Many friends of the movement, alarmed 
 and disgusted by the levelling doctrines which had per- 
 meated the political clubs, withdrew their support from 
 motions for reform, which seemed tainted with Jaco- 
 binism. Burke, formerly the champion of electoral 
 reform, now included this in his list of the deadly sins 
 of democracy. Pitt asserted that the time was inoppor- 
 tune for considering resolutions similar to those which
 
 14 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 he had repeatedly urged in the previous decade; and 
 the end of the century saw the prospects of democracy 
 gloomier even than amidst the torpor of 1780. Then 
 there was the apathy of ignorance and sheer Saxon 
 stolidity : now there was a keen sense of disgust at the 
 facile perversion of French democracy by the baubles of 
 power skilfully dangled by Napoleon. The new creed 
 that promised to renovate the world had apparently led 
 only to the triumph of militarism and the spoliation of 
 neighbouring peoples by a nation which bowed its own 
 neck to the yoke in order the more completely to sub- 
 jugate others. 
 
 " I find nothing great : 
 
 Nothing is left which I can venerate; 
 
 So that almost a doubt within me springs 
 
 Of Providence, such emptiness at length 
 
 Seems at the heart of all things." 
 
 These were the feelings of Wordsworth, when now in 
 1803 he regarded the heart-breaking finale of all the wild 
 hopes and aspirations aroused by the French Revolution 
 of 1789, of which he had sung 
 
 " Bliss was it in that dawn to be alive ; 
 But to be young was very heaven". 
 
 Nor was it only the sensitive temperament of the poet 
 which acutely felt the disillusionment. The same tone 
 of pessimism pervades the writings of many of the 
 publicists of the day, who had welcomed the fall of the 
 Bastille as the beginning of a new era for the whole 
 human race. A new generation had to arise, oppressed 
 by other evils than those of war, distracted by new 
 social and industrial problems, before the ardour for 
 reform could revive; and when again it gathered strength, 
 its inspiration was drawn from native sources. 
 
 But, apart from the sudden chill which the personality 
 and career of Napoleon cast over English reformers,
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 15 
 
 there were other influences of a more directly practical 
 nature which led the younger leaders to adopt methods 
 consonant with the traditions of the land of Hampden. 
 Indeed, most of the men who had been imbued with 
 French Jacobinism passed away in the period 1793-1815, 
 or lived in exile, leaving" the venerable Major Cartwright 
 as almost the sole connecting link between the earlier 
 generation of reformers and those who now arose to 
 grapple with the grievances and problems bequeathed to 
 posterity by the war period. To his genial moderating 
 influence we may justly ascribe the good sense which 
 generally characterized the efforts of the young English 
 democrats. His influence it was which helped to turn 
 it back into the old paths, and held aloft the constitu- 
 tional programme of 1780 as the goal of popular striv- 
 ings. 
 
 The adoption of a practical scheme of reform, such 
 as could conceivably be gained by constitutional means, 
 was indeed the urgent need of the time. Never was the 
 United Kingdom in a more parlous state than when the 
 crowning triumph of Waterloo placed it at the head of 
 the nations. It was but a short distance from the Capi- 
 tol of military triumph to the Tarpeian rock of sedition 
 and civil strife. Four short years separated Waterloo 
 from Peterloo. Never has a nation been more perplexed 
 and dismayed by the sudden drop from glory to misery, 
 from national exultation to civil discord, than the people 
 of England in iSis. 1 In this sudden awakening from 
 the glamour of an unparalleled military triumph to the 
 stern realities unveiled by peace, we may find an ex- 
 planation of the rapid growth of a Radicalism which was 
 far more deeply rooted than that of 1780, and far more 
 practical than that of 1790. The industrial and social 
 
 1 Lowe in his Present State of England (1823), ch. 2, remarks how un- 
 expected, even by experienced financiers, was the misery which came with 
 the peace.
 
 16 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 causes contributing to this discontent accordingly claim 
 a brief review before we examine the resulting political 
 efforts. 
 
 Patriots who, in the year of Waterloo, looked solely 
 on the surface of things, very naturally concluded that 
 the might of England was unbounded. They pointed 
 to the growth of her revenue from ^19,258,000 in 1792 
 (the last year before the wars) to the gigantic total of 
 ^105,698,000 in 1814. What limits were there to her 
 resources, they exclaimed, when, in spite of enormous 
 losses in men and treasure, the prices of agricultural 
 produce and the rent of land had doubled within that 
 period? As for our manufactures, the annual value of 
 our exports of cotton goods had trebled in the years 
 1801-1814; and the growing wealth of the community 
 was attested by the increasingly luxurious manners 
 adopted by our upper and middle classes. All this was 
 undeniably true. It aroused the wonder and admiration 
 of Mr. Colquhoun, author of The Resources of the British 
 Empire, at the growth of wealth which seemed to be 
 unchecked even by all the waste of warfare. 
 
 Had these cheery optimists pursued their researches 
 further, they would probably have found that much of 
 the prosperity was of a wholly artificial character. A 
 good deal of it was due to the war expenditure ; and the 
 expenditure of energy and wealth in warfare is no more 
 nutritive than the process of "feeding a dog on its own 
 tail". Though the propertied classes gallantly met the 
 annual claim of two shillings in the pound on their 
 incomes, yet most of the financial burden was bequeathed 
 to future generations. After Waterloo, the nation had 
 to bear the burden of a national debt which amounted 
 in all to more than ^861,000,000, entailing a yearly 
 interest of ^32, 600,000. When we remember that the 
 currency had been debased by an influx of paper notes 
 of doubtful value, we can realize the intensity of the 
 
 (H416)
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 17 
 
 strain resulting- from the return to ordinary conditions of 
 industrial and financial life. We can also understand 
 the popularity gained by that wrong-headed, warm- 
 hearted champion of the working-classes, William Cob- 
 bett, when he exclaimed to many an excited crowd that 
 the country could not and must not bear this burden, 
 but must make a clean sweep of the debt and then start 
 clear. It was, indeed, a working-man's question, when 
 the debt imposed an annual charge of thirty shillings 
 per head on every inhabitant of these islands, and when 
 that burden rested mainly on the necessaries of life and 
 the means of production. In this grievance is to be 
 found the chief motive power of democratic movements 
 after i8i5. 1 But, besides piling up an enormous debt, 
 the war bequeathed many other difficulties of an indus- 
 trial and social nature. The supremacy of our industries 
 and of our commerce was very largely the result of the 
 Napoleonic wars. Our land had undergone none of 
 those invasions which had all but ruined the trade and 
 industries of every continental country. After Trafalgar 
 our merchantmen sailed in comparative safety, while 
 French ships, and even those of the neutrals, were well- 
 nigh swept off the seas; and even our mighty foe con- 
 fessed the collapse of his efforts to strangle British trade 
 when his agents ordered English cloaks to supply the 
 French troops campaigning on the Vistula, and sugar 
 from the British West Indies for the imperial table. 
 England was the middleman between the Continent of 
 Europe and the rest of the world. 2 But would her 
 monopoly survive the advent of peace? Would not 
 rather her manufacturers and merchant princes be ruined 
 when trade resumed its natural course? The question 
 
 1 At the end of his Political Register of Oct. 5, 1816, Cobbett confidently 
 prophesies that the national debt will lead to parliamentary reform. 
 
 3 1 have treated this question in my article ' ' Napoleon and English Com- 
 merce", in the English Historical Review of Oct. 1893. 
 Ai (M416) B
 
 i8 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 was indeed most serious ; and but for our rapid advances 
 in labour-saving machinery, we might have suffered a 
 complete collapse. As it was, the value of our cotton 
 goods exported sank from ^"20,600,000 in 1815, to an 
 average of ; 16,400,000 for the next decade; while the 
 decline in the value of the woollen goods exported was 
 so persistent as not to be made up, until the reforms of 
 Sir Robert Peel breathed new life into our industries. 
 
 The gravity of the social crisis which faced us after 
 Waterloo will be realized if we glance very briefly at the 
 industrial changes then progressing in our land. The in- 
 vention of spinning-machines by Hargreaves, Crompton, 
 and others in the years 1764-1779, and the subsequent 
 application of steam-power had already begun to ruin 
 the spinning-wheel industry, by which wives and daugh- 
 ters had often kept the wolf from the door; and after 
 1803 Dr. Cartwright's power-loom began to press hard 
 on hand-loom weavers. Toil as these Silas Marners 
 might, they could not successfully compete with untiring 
 machinery, every improvement in which reduced the 
 price of cloth, and ground them down into the ever- 
 rising stratum of wage-earners. Two facts will suffice 
 to illustrate the magnitude of the changes brought 
 about by the alchemy of steam-power. Mr. Gaskell, the 
 author of a work Artisans and Machinery, has com- 
 puted that the cost price of a "piece" of cloth of the 
 same quality was reduced in the years 18001820 from 
 twenty-five to eight shillings; and that enlightened 
 manufacturer, Robert Owen, whose social aims will be 
 described in the following chapter, stated to a committee 
 of the House of Commons in 1816 that the cotton-mills 
 of Great Britain were then producing as much as could 
 be made by eighty millions of operatives working with- 
 out machinery. These startling assertions reveal the 
 causes of our wealth during the great war when the 
 Continental peoples were industrially dependent on us,
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 19 
 
 and of the distress which overtook us when those nations, 
 turning- to the pursuits of peace, began to imitate our 
 inventions and encroach on our markets. The brunt of 
 the distress caused by over-production and the fall of 
 prices, was of course felt most acutely by the wage- 
 earners, who clustered about that cheerless nucleus of 
 modern life the factory. 
 
 But the misery, which was to be the chief propelling 
 power of democracy in England, was fed from yet an- 
 other source. Side by side with these industrial changes, 
 an agricultural revolution had slowly but surely ruined 
 our sturdy yeomen farmers, and had often dispossessed 
 peasants of small but invaluable rights over common 
 fields and common pasturage. The chang-es had begun 
 in the earlier half of the previous century, when the 
 general cultivation of root-crops broke up the old waste- 
 ful system of farming on the open fields and necessitated 
 enclosure and the application of improved methods. But 
 these changes, which, according to Arthur Young, might 
 have been beneficial even to the peasantry had they been 
 carried out gradually and wisely, were forced on with 
 feverish activity under the stimulus of the great war, 
 when the price of wheat often rose to 6 a quarter. 
 The Napoleonic war cut us off from free intercourse 
 with the Baltic lands, on which we had mainly to rely; 
 the United States were closed to our ships ; and no one 
 had ever dreamt of importing corn from La Plata and 
 India, much less from our feeble settlements in Australia. 
 In face of the risk of actual famine which confronted us 
 in wet summers, there was every need to increase the 
 yield of corn ; and long experience had shown that this 
 could only be achieved by enclosing the open fields, 
 often worked on the old communal system, and by adopt- 
 ing improved methods of husbandry on large holdings. 
 As many as 1931 parishes in England and Wales applied 
 to Parliament during the war period for powers to enclose
 
 20 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 their "open " fields and common lands; and even when, 
 after Waterloo, prices fell to their normal level, enclosures 
 continued in diminished numbers. 
 
 The chief results of these enclosures were an enormous 
 increase in the agricultural wealth of the country, and a 
 lamentable falling off in the independence of the peas- 
 antry. 
 
 " 111 fares the land, to hastening ills a prey, 
 Where wealth accumulates and men decay." 
 
 Thus Goldsmith had warned us of the social evils which 
 would result from the enclosure of commons; and the 
 vision of the poet was on the whole as true as the argu- 
 ments of the agricultural reformers who advocated the 
 change. Many a parish was severely crippled by the 
 expense of gaining the special act of Parliament which 
 was required; and the reallotment of the common fields 
 and wastes gave many opportunities for sheer robbery. 
 In these cases, we may imagine, the iron of injustice 
 drove deep into the minds of the dispossessed cotters, 
 as they left the country, or sank to the position of wage- 
 earners. Even where there was no fraud, the poor and 
 the shiftless benefited little by a change which demanded 
 the application of skill, energy, and capital to the soil. 
 Myriads of peasants who had jogged along comfortably 
 on the produce of their arable plots and pasturage rights, 
 eking it out, perhaps, by work at the spinning-wheel and 
 the hand-loom, now saw all hope of independence vanish 
 when science came to be applied to agriculture as well 
 as to manufactures. Previously they had been half 
 "manufacturers", half farmers; but the specialization 
 of callings which marks the nineteenth century was 
 sooner or later fatal to their nondescript existence. 
 They fell, as it were, between two stools; and those 
 who had neither the money nor the energy to become 
 skilled manufacturers or successful farmers, sank to the
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 21 
 
 position of day-labourers on the land, or floated away 
 as social drift-wood into the seething eddies of the new 
 factory townships. 
 
 In his thoughtful inquiry into the development of 
 human society, Mr. Kidd has pointed out that changes 
 which have developed the nation's resources have been 
 fatal to the independence and welfare of the individual. 
 It may be questioned whether the remark is as widely 
 applicable as is claimed by that able writer. But it 
 certainly is true of the manufacturing and agricultural 
 changes which were in progress at the time of the great 
 war. The events of the war rendered those changes far 
 more sudden, and therefore more harmful to our social 
 system, than they would otherwise have been. The 
 monopoly enjoyed by our manufacturers and merchants 
 during the war gave to our trade an unhealthy stimulus, 
 the ruinous effects of which were acutely felt after the 
 return to ordinary conditions. The same remark applies 
 to our rural life. The monopoly in food-supply enjoyed 
 by our landlords and farmers in these islands forced on 
 a change which might perhaps otherwise have been 
 gradual and devoid of evil social results. The nation 
 was saved from financial ruin by being able suddenly to 
 draw upon two almost unworked sources of wealth ; but 
 the drain was really at the expense of future vitality. 
 Our commerce and agriculture were apparently never so 
 flourishing as in the year of Waterloo ; but the show of 
 prosperity was gained at the expense of industrial and 
 social changes which were deeply resented by our 
 working-classes. 
 
 There were special reasons why this resentment should 
 take a political form. Any inquiry into the details of 
 public expenditure sufficed to convict government of 
 reckless extravagance and a shameless prodigality in 
 the bestowal of sinecures. Indeed, many a champion 
 of retrenchment and reform jumped to the wholly erro-
 
 22 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 neous conclusion that the war against Napoleon had 
 been got up for the benefit of the governing classes. 
 This contention, as absurd as it was unpatriotic, very 
 properly doomed the opposition to impotence, until the 
 great struggle for European independence had been 
 fought and won. The dawn of peace tended to restore 
 the old relations of parties. The Tories were the cham- 
 pions not only of monarchical prerogatives, but also of 
 many of the regulations adopted by Pitt and his fol- 
 lowers to check the progress of French democratic ideas. 
 The Whig party, which had been cleft asunder by the 
 schism of Burke and Fox, and had been further weakened 
 by the adoption of a nagging anti-national policy through 
 the war period, now began to recover something of its old 
 prestige. Not that it had as yet definitely adopted the 
 policy of parliamentary reform. Disgusted by the failure 
 of democracy on the Continent, and by the schism which 
 it had caused in the once formidable Whig party, the 
 leaders held suspiciously aloof from this dangerous 
 principle until the efforts of working-men democrats 
 again forced the question into the sphere of ' ' practical 
 politics ". For the present, only the more adventurous 
 Whigs lent any support to " radical reformers " in their 
 efforts to annul or mitigate the harsh legislation of 
 the war period. The independent attitude of artisan 
 reformers can readily be understood in the light of 
 partisan politics of the time, and by the lurid glare shed 
 from industrial and agrarian grievances. Thefr industrial 
 independence was gone ; they had become wage-earners, 
 and yet they were forbidden by law to combine for any 
 purpose. Prevented from combination for a rise of 
 wages, they saw Parliament pass a law which seemed 
 to be designed solely to keep up the price of corn in the 
 interests of landlords and farmers. Indignation made 
 them politicians. The determination to gain the right 
 of combination in trade-unions, and to secure bread
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 23 
 
 at its natural price, inevitably led the leaders of the 
 labouring classes to press for a drastic measure of electoral 
 reform. Out of the depressing- conditions of their homes 
 discontent arose as naturally as malaria from a marsh. 
 With little artificial aid from any agitators, except from 
 one who will presently be noticed, the two most 
 characteristic working-class movements of our day 
 Trade-unionism and Chartism began to gather force 
 and volume. The former aimed at confronting master 
 manufacturers with an equality of power; while the 
 Radicals, and later the Chartists, hoped to restore to the 
 working-classes all, and more than all, their old rights 
 through the instrumentality of Parliament. 
 
 It was natural that the attention of working-men 
 should first be directed to electoral reform. In the 
 autumn of 1815 our legislators passed the famous Corn 
 Law, with the aim of keeping up the average price of 
 wheat to about eighty shillings per quarter, a price 
 which was declared to be "reasonable between the 
 farmer, landlord, and public ". Until home corn had 
 reached that price, foreign corn was to be completely 
 excluded from our ports. Had this Corn Law been 
 passed as a temporary expedient for preventing the 
 sudden collapse of our greatest industry, few reasonable 
 men would have agitated against it. The average price 
 of wheat in the previous five years had been close on a 
 hundred shillings a quarter; and the farmers, whose toil 
 had saved the country from starvation, might reasonably 
 claim some guarantee against a headlong fall in the 
 price of corn, such as might probably result from the 
 advent of peace. But the Parliament of landlords ap- 
 parently desired that the Corn Law of 1815 should be 
 permanent, and that the rapid growth of our population 
 should drive wheat up to a price which now appeared 
 "reasonable" to them, though it was nearly double the 
 average price of the years 1760-1790. The men of
 
 24 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 London and Westminster made vehement demonstra- 
 tions against the bill during its discussion. It was in 
 vain. The bill became law. The marked preference 
 thus shown for the interests of the country over those of 
 the towns led to various disturbances. Bakers' shops 
 were pillaged; and the popular excitement, after once 
 breaking bounds, portended indiscriminate destruction. 
 Bands of operatives roamed through the factory town- 
 ships, smashing the new hated machines; and dis- 
 charged soldiers and sailors often joined the rioters, to 
 show their hatred of a government which neglected them 
 while it pampered the Prince Regent and his minions. 
 Amidst the ferment in the towns the followers of a Dr. 
 Spence, who desired a general levelling of property, 
 found a favourable opportunity of disseminating their 
 ideas ; and, as will presently appear, one of their meet- 
 ings was to have a noteworthy result. Misery breeds 
 political nostrums as rapidly as an epidemic favours the 
 sale of quack remedies: and it may be questioned 
 whether the English public has ever been so plied with 
 infallible recipes of the "Morrison" type as in the 
 generation succeeding Waterloo. That an ignorant 
 populace, when oppressed by grievous burdens, when per- 
 plexed by strange symptoms, when distracted by rival 
 nostrums, should ultimately have selected the means 
 which have peacefully tended to the healing of the body 
 politic, argues a statesmanlike instinct which is surely 
 unequalled in the world's history. Among the restora- 
 tive processes which have been at work, democracy of 
 the English type may certainly be reckoned as one of 
 the chief. We are now in a position to understand the 
 chief steps in the renovation of the nation's life. 
 
 The outlook in 1816 was certainly gloomy. States- 
 men and people were alike perplexed by the increase of 
 misery and discontent, when they had looked for peace 
 and prosperity. The discontent, though wide-spread,
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 25 
 
 was vague and purposeless, until by the action of a 
 group of Radicals, whose chief thinkers will be noticed 
 in the next chapter, it became concentrated on a demand 
 for a complete reform of Parliament. Foremost among 
 the more popular champions of Radicalism stands a burly 
 and pugnacious personage who claims some attention. 
 
 Few Englishmen of this century have exerted a wider 
 and more powerful influence on the progress of demo- 
 cracy than William Cobbett. His position as the first 
 English newspaper editor who caught the ear of the 
 people and made the press a permanent power, would 
 entitle him to notice here, even if he had not given a 
 powerful impulse to parliamentary reform. That he did 
 not earn for himself the higher renown of a legislative 
 reformer was due to the strange defects which marred 
 an otherwise striking character. His personality, like 
 his career, is a tissue of inconsistencies and contradictions. 
 The son of a farmer of Farnham in Surrey, he spent his 
 youth as a copying clerk in Gray's Inn. To escape 
 from this drudgery, he enlisted as a soldier and served 
 for seven years under the union-jack in Nova Scotia, 
 occupying his leisure time there with study and court- 
 ship. Returning to England, he obtained his discharge 
 in 1791 and proceeded to France, where he learnt the 
 language and declaimed against the Revolution with all 
 the fervour of a devoted royalist. On the approach of 
 war between France and England, he set sail for 
 America; and, as a bookseller in Philadelphia, he strove, 
 in a paper called the Porcupine, to prick the bubbles of 
 democratic enthusiasm. The success of his royalist 
 propaganda may be measured by his own statement, 
 that there were in that city about ten thousand persons 
 who would have rejoiced to see him murdered, while not 
 more than fifty would have stirred an inch to save him. 
 He next flitted to his native shores, there to live in the 
 turmoil ever dear to him ; and as the English government
 
 26 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 was exceedingly unpopular, he gave it the support of 
 his fretful quills. But a change came over the spirit 
 of the Porcupine, or the Weekly Register as he now re- 
 named it. A slight from the frigid William Pitt changed 
 the loyalty of the editor to bitter dislike of the govern- 
 ment, which was later on envenomed by the imposition 
 of a heavy fine and two years' imprisonment for certain 
 libellous articles. Thenceforth the cloak of Tom Paine 
 fell on Cobbett's shoulders, together with a double 
 portion of his mordant powers of sarcasm and abuse. 
 He reduced the price of his Register to twopence, and 
 held up to execration not only the government but all 
 who differed from him. He therefore had abundant 
 materials at hand for his facile pen. The abuses of 
 government were notorious; and his impulsive and 
 vindictive temperament constantly brought him into 
 collision with nearly all prominent men, even those of 
 the opposition. The Radical member for Westminster, 
 Sir Francis Burdett, on whom Cobbett had showered 
 praises as the saviour of the country, was suddenly de- 
 nounced as the type of all that was mean and base; 
 Hunt "the patriot" shrank into Hunt "the greatest of 
 liars" ; and O'Connell, from being "the glory of Ireland", 
 was execrated as "a vile vagabond ". Genial and good- 
 natured though he was at home, stout and hearty 
 though he was in physique, Cobbett almost rivalled 
 Rousseau in the morbid sensitiveness which was ever 
 detecting imaginary insults, and in the persistence with 
 which he nursed his revenge. Such men may initiate a 
 movement, but they are the ruin of every party or asso- 
 ciation which they seek to found or regulate. 
 
 And yet the bluff south countryman was not without 
 his sterling qualities. His determination to educate 
 himself and his fellows was to have a most important 
 influence on English working-men of that period. His 
 sketches of home-life and of the joy of training a family
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 27 
 
 revealed new possibilities to the men of that generation ; 
 and in his Rural Rides, the descriptions of scenery and 
 the dog-like patience of our peasantry are presented with 
 the freshness and pathos of Rousseau himself. The 
 enormous mass and unfailing vigour of his writings 
 evoked from the Standard the startling statement that 
 he was unrivalled since the time of Swift for clearness, 
 force, and power of copious illustration. For "twenty- 
 nine years eleven weeks only excepted" his weekly 
 paper regularly appeared to excite the interest or the 
 passions of our people. It is true that its variety and 
 vigour were largely due to the almost canine pugnacity 
 of the editor, and to other qualities which favour the 
 output of "copy". So numerous were the water-tight 
 compartments of his brain that he could freely dismiss 
 the memory of past errors and gleefully proceed to 
 alienate newly -made allies or cudgel another set of 
 opponents, while the vigour and sustained power of his 
 attacks gained the admiration of an athletic people, even 
 apart from the respect felt for his manly exposure of 
 political abuses. 
 
 Such was the man who now led the popular demand 
 for a drastic reform of Parliament. In his paper of 
 October 26, 1816, he demanded that the House of Com- 
 mons should be elected annually by all the tax-payers of 
 the land', and that all other questions should be secondary 
 to this. " Let us have this reform first, and all other 
 good things will be given unto us." This determined 
 agitation commenced by Cobbett may be considered the 
 definite commencement of Radicalism in its nineteenth- 
 century guise. Others, it is true, had agitated for yet 
 larger demands; but, for reasons which we have now 
 considered, they had made no permanent impression 
 on our people. Now, however, amidst the distress 
 which followed on the great war, Cobbett's agitation 
 was to have important results.
 
 2 8 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Samuel Bamford, a weaver of Middleton near Man- 
 chester, records in his memoirs that the comparative 
 absence of riots after 1816 was due to Cobbett's advice 
 to working-men to agitate for a complete reform of 
 Parliament, and that they thenceforth became deliberate 
 and systematic in their proceedings. They started 
 "Hampden Clubs" in all the towns and villages of 
 South Lancashire, and speakers crossed the Pennines 
 to stir up the more apathetic Yorkshiremen. Delegates 
 of the federated clubs drew up a political programme 
 which demanded annual election of Parliaments; exclu- 
 sion of all "placemen"; that every man of more than 
 eighteen years of age, who paid taxes, should have a 
 vote ; that every 20,000 inhabitants should send a member 
 to the House of Commons; and that "talent and virtue 
 should be the only qualifications necessary" for mem- 
 bers. 
 
 This early stage of the Radical movement was marked 
 at least in the provinces by a constant reliance on 
 moral suasion, and by a determination to hand over to 
 the police any who advocated violent methods. But the 
 more impressionable Londoners provoked a contest with 
 the government, which marred the prospects of the 
 movement. The pillage of shops consequent on a mass 
 meeting held in November, 1816, at Spa Fields, near 
 Islington, was followed by repressive measures of so 
 drastic a nature that freedom of speech and of meeting 
 was, for the time, at an end ; and Cobbett retired to 
 America. 1 These measures roused so bitter a feeling in 
 the Hampden Clubs, that several of the Scottish clubs 
 bound themselves by oath to further their cause "either 
 by moral or by physical strength, as the case may re- 
 
 1 Even the Union Debating Society at Cambridge was for a time sup- 
 pressed. Macaulay, then at Trinity College, had a striking proof of the 
 results of suppressing public meetings. While the townsmen were asserting 
 their indignation in a riot, the future historian received a dead cat full in 
 the face.
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 29 
 
 quire" the first sign of that divergence of aim which 
 later on was to divide the Chartists. 
 
 Indeed, the Radical movement of the years 1816-1819 
 curiously foreshadows the Chartist movement, which 
 was to be its complete expression. There was at both 
 epochs a desire on the part of nearly all the first leaders 
 to pursue strictly legal methods; there was the same 
 growth of indignation among the masses of the people 
 at the apathy of Parliament; the same split into the 
 "moral force" and "physical force" sections, the same 
 collapse of the efforts of the more daring spirits, and the 
 same final gain of the more practicable proposals of the 
 "moral force" men. 
 
 The breach between the operatives and Parliament 
 yawned wider in the years 1817 to 1819. The deepen- 
 ing distress of those years, enhanced by a return from a 
 paper-money system to cash payments, would alone have 
 produced rebellious feelings ; but these were fanned into 
 a flame by the lavish expenditure on pensions, sinecures, 
 and the tawdry splendour of the Regent's court. The 
 Hampden Clubs, debarred from open debate, began to 
 drill their members, ostensibly for the more orderly 
 management of great mass meetings, when these, in 
 1818, again became legal; but their ulterior aim pro- 
 bably was to overawe Parliament by a display of physical 
 force.- Yet, even in these mass meetings the proceedings 
 were at first quite orderly. The men of Birmingham 
 adopted a novel method of protesting against the elec- 
 toral absurdities which excluded their town from direct 
 representation in Parliament, and gave to thirteen Cor- 
 nish villages far more legislative power than was then 
 enjoyed by all the new manufacturing towns of Great 
 Britain. On the advice of the veteran reformer Major 
 Cartwright, the citizens of the great midland town 
 assembled in mass meeting and chose a Radical Stafford- 
 shire baronet, Sir Charles Wolseley, to act as "legisla-
 
 30 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 torial attorney" for Birmingham, and to present their 
 claims in person to the House of Commons. Had they 
 acted in the spirit of our old English constitution, they 
 might with equal reason have sent him as their member; 
 for it is certain that the Witan, or councillors who 
 shared with the Saxon kings the right of making laws, 
 were chosen by the shout of the people at their folk- 
 moots. There was nothing revolutionary in the action 
 of the men of Birmingham; but unluckily their legisla- 
 torial attorney, inflated with pride at his unique title, 
 uttered a seditious harangue at Stockport, which lodged 
 him in the county jail. Nothing daunted, the men of 
 Manchester determined to elect a " legislatorial attorney", 
 and arranged a monster meeting to be held in St. Peter's 
 Field, just outside their town, under the presidency of 
 "Orator" Hunt. 
 
 Their choice of a chairman could scarcely have been 
 more unwise, had they designed to arouse the fears of 
 the rich and the passions of the poor. Society had made 
 Henry Hunt lord of the manor of Glastonbury; but 
 nature had made him an agitator. His restless tempera- 
 ment, fluent tongue, powerful voice, and morbid vanity, 
 found in the mass meetings of the north a more con- 
 genial sphere than in the humdrum proceedings of the 
 court leet of Glastonbury. That the storms of Parlia- 
 ment called forth his best efforts may be seen in this 
 contemporary sketch of him in Blackwood's Magazine : 
 "A comely, tall, rosy, white-headed, mean-looking, well- 
 gartered tradesman, of, I take it, 60. His only merits 
 are his impudence and his voice, both unique. In vain 
 do all sides of the House of Commons unite to cough, 
 shuffle, groan, and shout. He pauses for a moment, 
 until the clamour is at its height, and then, re-pitching 
 his notes, apparently without an effort, lifts his halloo 
 as clear and distinct above the storm as ever ye heard a 
 minster bell tolling over the racket of a village wake."
 
 The Origin of English Radicalism. 31 
 
 These powers, however, count for little unless controlled 
 and directed by a well-balanced brain, of the possession 
 of which Hunt could not be accused by his bitterest foes. 
 In his nature the emotions held unchallenged sway; and 
 his rancorous oratory helped to infect a whole generation 
 with a passion for invective, until the quieter style of 
 Cobden and Bright restored to our platform oratory its 
 earlier dignity. When Hunt faced a throng of reformers 
 to ventilate some grievance, his figure seemed instinct 
 with suppressed fury; his eyes became distended and 
 almost blood-shot; his griped hand beat the air as if to 
 annihilate the Tory ministers; and his whole manner 
 betokened a vehemence of passion which at times could 
 scarcely find utterance. With such a chairman, the St. 
 Peter's Field meeting could scarcely fail to end in a 
 " Peterloo". 
 
 Secret drills on the Lancashire moors had also alarmed 
 the authorities ; and when dense columns of men began 
 to march to Manchester on the morning of August 12, 
 the troops and the yeomanry were held in readiness. 
 Yet the operatives of Lancashire carried no arms ; they 
 were dressed in their Sunday best; and the laurels 
 carried by their front ranks betokened a peaceable 
 demonstration, as was further shown by the mottoes on 
 their banners "Liberty and Fraternity", "Parliaments 
 Annual", "Suffrage Universal", and "No Corn Laws". 
 One black banner, displaying the threatening words 
 "Equal Representation or Death", seemed to recall the 
 times of Danton and Marat; but in general the vast 
 demonstration promised an observance of the best tradi- 
 tions ot the land of Hampden. 
 
 A mighty shout was raised when Hunt appeared on 
 the wagons that formed the hustings, and yet the 
 magistrates determined to serve then and there the writ 
 of arrest which the orator had brought on himself by 
 some frothy talk about the bloody butchers of Waterloo.
 
 32 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 The constables bearing the writ, and their escort of 
 yeomanry, were soon wedged in among the crowd; 
 whereupon the magistrates ordered the hussars to liber- 
 ate the volunteer horsemen, who were now beginning to 
 ply their swords in grim earnest. As the cavalry swept 
 into the densely-packed field, the crowd broke into a 
 panic-stricken rush ; and the space which had been filled 
 with a good-humoured, orderly throng, speedily became 
 a scene of wild disorder, strewn with torn banners, 
 maimed and bleeding figures, and ghastly heaps of 
 writhing humanity at the further edge of the field. 
 There were comparatively few deaths, for the hussars 
 never disgraced their swords by using the edge; but 
 the wounds lavishly dealt by the volunteer horsemen 
 aroused a feeling of class hatred, which was intensified 
 when government approved the action of the magistrates 
 and struck a medal in honour of the exploits of the 
 yeomanry. The gag was again stringently applied by 
 Parliament in the repressive measures known as the Six 
 Acts ; and the tide of democratic feeling was dammed up 
 for a time, until, gathering strength from sheer indigna- 
 tion, it swept away many of the old oligarchical barriers 
 in the Reform Bill of 1832. 
 
 Chapter II. 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 
 
 The foregoing sketch of the Radical movement of 
 1816-1819 is a necessary introduction to the study of the 
 later democratic movement; for only those who have 
 realized the orderly character of the earlier democratic 
 agitation, and the indignation caused by its brutal re- 
 pression, can possibly understand either the pent-up
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 33 
 
 enthusiasm for reform which forced on the measure of 
 1832, or the disappointment at its immediate results. 
 
 But other influences were also at work, tending to 
 discredit our old political system and to emphasize the 
 demand for reform. An intellectual movement was 
 gathering such force as to portend ruin to all institutions 
 which could not justify their existence. In the France 
 of 1789 the crash of the revolutionary storm had been 
 heralded by premonitory mutterings and by protests of 
 leading thinkers; and so too in England the same 
 warnings might be observed by the weather-wise. A 
 great Italian thinker has said that ideas rule the world, 
 and that what we call a revolution is but the passage of 
 an idea from theory to practice. Certain it is that no 
 great and abiding change has ever taken place in the 
 body politic without some premonition from the brain 
 politic. The general course of the reform movement 
 was what had been foretold by our chief thinkers, the 
 most prominent among whom, in the years 1800-1830, 
 was Jeremy Bentham. 
 
 It would be far beyond the scope of this little work to 
 attempt a description of the utilitarian philosophy. Its 
 connection with politics, especially with the philosophic 
 Radicalism of which Bentham was the founder, may, 
 however, be understood from the central principle of his 
 creed the promotion of "the greatest happiness of the 
 greatest number". His whole system of ethics and 
 politics was severely utilitarian. It may indeed be 
 compared to an arch, which has as its key-stone this 
 principle, serving to unite his theoretical and political 
 speculations, and to interlock them in a dogmatic whole. 
 The new creed was soon to prove itself subversive of 
 modes of thought and of institutions which rested only 
 on prescription and tradition. Utility was a crucial test 
 when rigorously applied to the Gothic irregularities of 
 the British constitution; and Bentham was nothing if 
 
 ( M 416 ) C
 
 34 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 not rigorous. 1 Exact methods of thought and reasoning 
 were to be the sole guide of the philosophic and political 
 inquirer. Sentiment, devotion, chivalry, appeals to the 
 continuity of national life, all were excluded from the 
 argument ; and man was treated as if he were merely a 
 reasoning machine, solely intent on manufacturing enjoy- 
 ment by logical processes. The archaic dogmatism of 
 the divine right of kings, the newer but equally severe 
 dogmatism of Rousseau and the framers of the rights 
 of man, were alike swept aside, because they lacked all 
 proof of their utility or reality. But, as generally happens 
 with destroyers of dogma, Bentham cleared the way for 
 a new and formidable dogmatism, when he insisted on 
 the undisputed sway of the principle of utility in politics. 
 Imbued with the very one-sided and almost self-cancelling 
 theory that man was a reasoning creature engaged in a 
 constant pursuit after happiness, Bentham arraigned 
 the institutions of his country at the utilitarian judg- 
 ment bar. Monarchy was condemned, the king being 
 sentenced as the " corrupter general" of society. Aris- 
 tocracy fared no better. Democracy, however, was pro- 
 nounced to be the sole form of rational government, 
 because as each man sought his own happiness, the 
 government of the majority would necessarily pursue 
 the interests and the happiness of that majority. Ben- 
 tham's contempt of history (which is in essence the 
 record of man's experience in his civic relations) here led 
 him into an unwarrantable assumption. Omitting all 
 consideration of the morality, or immorality, of the 
 claim, it does not follow that the collective action of 
 great masses of men will lead to results similar to 
 those gained by individuals. Still more egregious is 
 his blunder in assuming that what the majority aim at, 
 that they will realize. 
 
 1 "To know the true good of the community is what constitutes the 
 science of legislation ; the art consists in finding the means to realize that 
 good" (Bentham, Principles of Legislation, ch. i).
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 35 
 
 We must remember, however, that while Bentham's 
 contention for an unlimited democracy is logically un- 
 satisfactory, even on his own premisses, yet his scathing- 
 criticism of absurd laws and odious sinecures was pro- 
 ductive of immediate and also of far-reaching benefit. 1 
 It nerved with enthusiasm an eager band of disciples, 
 dubbed Benthamites by the public, to attempt a crusade 
 in and out of Parliament against the abuses of the 
 Georgian regime. Joseph Hume, the father of the 
 movement for retrenchment and reform, was reinforced 
 in his hitherto almost single-handed struggle against 
 official corruption ; and a brilliant group of men, among 
 whom were James Mill, and his yet more gifted son, John 
 Stuart Mill, along with Fonblanque, Buller, and others, 
 resolved to start a distinctively Radical review in which 
 to assert utilitarian principles. The result was the famous 
 Westminster Review. Its first number, which appeared 
 in April, 1824, contained an incisive attack on the Whigs 
 from the pen of the elder Mill. Beginning with a survey 
 of the British constitution, he showed its thoroughly 
 aristocratic character, seeing that a few hundred families 
 could return a majority of the House of Commons. He 
 then exhibited the tendency of an aristocracy to divide 
 into two factions ; whence it would naturally result that 
 if one party became securely installed in power the other 
 (the Whigs) would endeavour to oust them by invoking 
 the aid of public opinion, "without any essential sacri- 
 fice of aristocratical predominance". This and this alone 
 was the meaning of the occasional coquettings of the 
 Whigs with popular principles, as also of their chief 
 literary organ, the Edinburgh Review, in its skilful " see- 
 saw" policy on public affairs. The article is noteworthy 
 
 1 Especially in strengthening the demand for legal reform. " Bentham 
 found the philosophy of law what English practising lawyers had made it, 
 a mess." ..." Glory be to Bentham that he has been the Hercules of 
 this hydra " (J. S. Mill's Essay on Bentham). See also Sir F. Pollock's 
 History of the Science of Politics, p. 102.
 
 36 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 as the literary tUbut of that new philosophic Radicalism, 
 which was to play an important part in the formation 
 of public opinion. So pronounced, indeed, was the in- 
 tellectual movement towards democratic reform that the 
 younger Mill, in endeavouring to found a select political 
 debating society, found his chief difficulty to lie in the 
 dearth of defenders of existing institutions. 
 
 Events also seemed to be moving quickly even in the 
 unreformed Parliament. The repeal, in 1824-1825, of 
 the old statutes prohibiting combinations of workmen 
 enabled our artisans to form trade -unions, thereby 
 checking, at least in some industries, that fall in wages 
 which economists declared to be inevitable; besides 
 which, the power of combination for trade purposes was 
 to have no slight influence in the formation of political 
 clubs. The abolition of religious disabilities, under which 
 Protestant Dissenters and Roman Catholics had long 
 suffered, were two noteworthy concessions to the prin- 
 ciple of religious liberty in the years 1828 and 1829 
 respectively. 
 
 But far more important was the earthquake shock of 
 the French Revolution of July, 1830, which dethroned 
 the unteachable Charles X. and destroyed the old legitim- 
 ist claims of monarchical divine right. The results of 
 this startling event were felt far beyond the bounds of 
 France. The apparently complete triumph of democracy 
 in Belgium, and the popular risings which ensued in 
 Germany, Italy, and Poland, seemed to betoken a speedy 
 end of the old order of things. In few lands did the 
 old and the new stand in more glaring contrast than in 
 the United Kingdom. On the one hand was a govern- 
 ment venerable with the prestige of ages, yet having 
 little vital connection with the people whose interests 
 it professed to serve. The ancient glory of the mon- 
 archy was now tarnished by the vulgar extravagance 
 and cynical immorality of "the first gentleman in
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 37 
 
 Europe ". With vice and selfishness enthroned, the 
 tone of fashionable society and of our public life may 
 readily be imagined. Thanks to the persistent labours 
 of Joseph Hume and a few other champions of economy, 
 some of the worst financial abuses had been probed and 
 the most shameless sinecures had been abolished; but 
 the game of politics was still the most interesting and 
 profitable of occupations, at least for the victors. A 
 whole generation spent in opposition had sufficed to 
 convert the bulk of the Whig party to the cause of 
 reform, for which, when in power, they had done so 
 little in the previous century. 
 
 Certainly they could now make out a good case 
 against the existing parliamentary system. By a strange 
 clinging to old customs, so characteristic of our race, 
 the old system of election and representation, which for 
 Plantagenet England was truly democratic, had under- 
 gone scarcely any change during more than two cen- 
 turies. The policy of the United Kingdom was largely 
 controlled by decayed boroughs or mere hamlets, which 
 were the political property of neighbouring magnates. 
 Out of the 658 members of the House of Commons, as 
 many as 424 were returned either on the nomination or 
 the recommendation of patrons; and it was notorious 
 that ^5000 was the average price paid by an aspirant 
 for political honours to the "borough -monger", the 
 bargain being often rounded off by the proviso that the 
 member should pay ^1000 for every year which he 
 passed in the parliamentary preserves. The inequalities 
 of the representation and of the franchise were equally 
 grotesque. Scotland returned forty-five members to 
 Parliament, and Cornwall returned forty-four; but this 
 inequality in individual voting power was not so great 
 as would appear on the surface, for in the whole of 
 Scotland there were less than five thousand voters. In 
 the parliamentary boroughs of Great Britain the fran-
 
 38 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 chise presented the strangest irregularities. In some 
 towns the mayor and corporation, in others the freemen, 
 returned the members to Parliament; while elsewhere 
 the right of voting was enjoyed by all who inhabited 
 tenements possessing a fireplace. Well might Heine 
 declare in 1830 that England was congealed in a medi- 
 aeval condition. But under the ice-bound surface of law 
 and custom there was rising a vernal flood-tide which 
 threatened a veritable debacle. The forces of nature 
 revealed by the great inventors, Hargreaves, Crompton, 
 Watt, and Stephenson, were working every year with 
 greater potency. A new England, grimy, amorphous, 
 but gifted with the irresistible expansiveness of a vigor- 
 ous life, was now beginning to burst the crust of the 
 old England. This new energy had no outlet in Parlia- 
 ment; it was scarcely recognized in the statute-book, 
 but it was now fully determined to assert its powers. 
 
 The contest between the squirearchy and the indus- 
 trial interest renewed in a nineteenth-century guise the 
 struggle ever going on in a progressive society between 
 the privileged and the non-privileged classes; but rarely 
 have the omens threatened civil disturbance more than 
 in the England of 1830. Burdened by an extravagant 
 court, a heedless Parliament, a crushing load of debt, its 
 social system warped and strained by an industrial revolu- 
 tion quite unparalleled in the annals of mankind, the 
 United Kingdom seemed beset with difficulties. The 
 onward rush of political ideas was at least as threatening 
 in pre-reform England as it had been in pre-revolu- 
 tionary France; and yet, though steam was being 
 rapidly generated in the out-worn governmental machine, 
 many of the engineers seemed to see safety only in 
 stopping the safety-valve. 
 
 A fortunate concurrence of circumstances saved us 
 from an explosion. George IV. conferred his only 
 benefit on this world by leaving it shortly before the
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 39 
 
 French Revolution of 1830; and the elections to a new 
 Parliament, held amid the excitement caused by that 
 event, sent up a majority of reformers to Westminster, 
 thus compelling" the old system to pronounce its own 
 doom, and installing- a Whig ministry under Earl Grey, 
 in place of that of the Duke of Wellington. The acces- 
 sion of the popular sailor king, William IV., who was 
 in favour of reform, further served to rally the people 
 around our old institutions and avert a catastrophe. A 
 measure was now drawn up by the cabinet, which pro- 
 posed to give votes to all tenants of a ,20 rental, but 
 on the protest of Lord Brougham, backed up by a mass 
 meeting of the men of Newcastle, the limit was extended 
 to " ten-pounders ". Another change was less satis- 
 factory. Lord Durham ardently desired to include in 
 the Reform Bill a proposal for voting by ballot, but this 
 was ruled out at the express wish of the prime-minister. 
 Yet, although the Reform Bill came far short of the 
 desires of thorough-going democrats, it elicited from so 
 ardent a reformer as Joseph Hume the statement that 
 he was surprised and gratified by its proposals. 
 
 Instead of telling the oft-told tale of the parliamentary 
 struggle for the Reform Bills of 1831 and 1832, it will 
 be more profitable and interesting to examine the artisan 
 movements of the time which prevented the famous Act 
 of 1832 from enjoying that finality which its champions 
 claimed for it. 
 
 Judging from the Whig historians and biographers, 
 one would draw the conclusion that the masses of the 
 people were completely unanimous in their support of 
 the Bill. Nothing could be more misleading. The 
 reformers, far from marching in a compact phalanx 
 against the oligarchical stronghold, formed two separate 
 columns of attack, one marching with all the pomp and 
 pageantry of war, the other ill-organized, leaderless, 
 preceded by no martial music, and mute, save for the
 
 40 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 defiant shouts which betokened its ardour. Even amidst 
 the assault, these allied forces viewed each other with 
 something of the dislike which exists between regulars 
 and guerrillas; and after the banner of reform was 
 planted on the walls of Old Sarum, the disputes which 
 had been occasionally heard amid all the din of battle, 
 burst forth with ever-increasing animosity. The course 
 of the reform struggle of 1831-1832 is of importance, not 
 only owing to the extension of the franchise which im- 
 mediately resulted, but also because it led the irregulars 
 to organize themselves, and draw up a programme, 
 which, as will be seen, contained nearly all the watch- 
 words of the Chartists. 
 
 The progress of this Radical vanguard has nowhere 
 been so well described as in the manuscript notes on 
 Working' Men's Associations, left by Mr. Francis Place 
 as materials to serve the historian of this period. In 
 these notes there is a mine of information as to the early 
 history of the Radical and Chartist movement; and their 
 value is enhanced by the usually calm and unbiassed 
 judgment of the writer. Francis Place was by trade 
 a master tailor, who had built up a good business at 
 Charing Cross; but his ambition was not limited to his 
 shop and his bank account. In the words of the old 
 Hebrew Scriptures, which attribute the characteristics 
 of certain callings to famous founders, we might say 
 that Place was the father of latter-day radical tailors. 
 His shop was a veritable Cave of Adullam, a resort for 
 all the disaffected who conspired to change the laws at 
 Westminster; and such was his organizing power and 
 quiet tenacity of purpose, that in 1824 he won a great 
 social and political triumph in skilfully preparing the way 
 for the abolition of the odious Combination Law of 1797, 
 which had crushed any trade -union of working-men. 
 His long investigation of the evil effects of state inter- 
 ference had made him a sturdy upholder of individual
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 41 
 
 liberty of the laisser faire type, and a decided opponent 
 of Robert Owen's State Socialism. He was therefore 
 well fitted to criticise the schemes of the Owenites, who 
 had so much to do with the drafting- of the Charter ; and 
 the thousands of neatly written pages of his Journal, 
 which is now in the British Museum, attest alike his 
 tailor-like neatness, his unimaginative dulness, and his 
 determination to be not only the chronicler but the 
 org-anizer of democratic movements. Occasionally the 
 suppressed fire of his resentment flashes forth, as in 
 the statement that the government of the country was 
 "a perpetual cheat, a fraudulent game at fictitious 
 honours and real emoluments, a continual practice of 
 pompous meanness founded on the absurd reverence the 
 people have long been taught to pay to the aristocracy". 
 But such outbursts rarely relieve the monotony of his 
 painfully precise narrative. Much as he hated the abuses 
 of the old oligarchy, he also saw the danger of events 
 moving too fast, and giving power to those who desired 
 to wipe out the national debt and effect a forcible re- 
 distribution of wealth. He trembled to see the feebleness 
 of the old order, and the scrambles for place of two 
 effete factions, eyed with growing malignity by the 
 democratic Caliban. The dangers of the time nerved 
 him to struggle for an advanced measure of reform 
 which should purify and strengthen the government, 
 and gain time for the instruction of the masses in the fit 
 use of the political power for which they were clamour- 
 ing. His apprehensions were shared by many even of 
 the advanced Radicals, who had good reason to know 
 how the leaven of communism was permeating our 
 working-classes, owing to the alluring teachings of 
 Robert Owen and Lieutenant Hodgkin. 
 
 As Robert Owen may justly be regarded as the founder 
 of English Socialism, Co-operation, and indirectly of 
 Chartism, a brief sketch of his views will not be out of
 
 43 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 place here. The strange chances which raised him from 
 the position of draper's apprentice to that of a partner 
 in a flourishing- firm of Manchester manufacturers, and 
 in 1800 installed him as chief partner at the New Lanark 
 Mills, imprinted on his quietly tenacious nature the 
 belief that external circumstances decided not only a 
 man's career, but also his whole character and conduct. 
 Fortunately for his work-people, this usually noxious 
 creed was transformed by the sunshine of his beneficent 
 nature into a source of life-giving activity and persistent 
 endeavour to mould his "hands" at New Lanark until 
 they should become "fully formed men and women". 
 Spacious dining and lecture halls attested his care for 
 their physical and mental welfare. His sale of provisions 
 to them at nearly cost price, and distribution of the profits 
 of this store, marked him out as the father of Co-opera- 
 tion in our land; and his profit-sharing arrangements 
 gained him the same honour in regard to "industrial 
 partnership ". But his plans embraced not only the 
 present welfare of his operatives, but also the perfecting 
 of the human race, by means of enlightened education 
 and equalization of opportunities. By beginning with 
 the young, even with the very infants, he so far succeeded 
 with the tough Scottish nature that he claimed for his 
 theories a universal application, and proposed to re- 
 generate the human race by mapping out the earth in 
 quadrangular communities, where, as some wag said, 
 everything was to be common except common sense. 
 Mankind, in fact, was to be born again in an ever-ex- 
 panding series of industrial parallelograms, where wealth 
 and poverty, religion and family life, were ultimately to 
 give place to the customs of an idealized rabbit warren. 
 Such was the prospect set forth in mild, yet inflexible 
 language by the prophet of New Lanark. It is not sur- 
 prising that amidst the deepening distress which followed 
 after Waterloo the more ardent of our operatives imbibed
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 43 
 
 these ideas with an enthusiasm which was not quickly 
 damped either by the dimness of the seer's vision into 
 the future, or by his rigorous autocracy in the arrange- 
 ment of details. Owen's visit to the United States gave 
 the more restively practical of his disciples the oppor- 
 tunity of starting co-operative societies on what they 
 thought to be workable lines, only to meet with a chilling 
 rebuke on the prophet's return. Dissensions hindered 
 the growth of the regenerating parallelograms as well 
 as of these early co-operative societies; but on the 
 collapse of the parent society the remaining members 
 started The National Union of the Working -classes 
 (April, 1831), in order to gain the political enfranchise- 
 ment which seemed to present the readiest means for 
 securing a redistribution of wealth and equality of 
 opportunity. The formation of this union was the 
 chief political result of the movement initiated by Owen. 
 It was the work of his followers, not of the seer himself; 
 for he ever regarded the new Radicalism with the sus- 
 picion and dislike natural to his autocratic character. 
 
 But there was another writer whose influence was, for 
 a time, scarcely second to that of Owen, namely, Lieu- 
 tenant Hodgkin. He seems to have injured his prospects 
 in the navy by a pamphlet on the injustice and iniquity 
 of the press-gang system. While vegetating on the 
 half-pay list, he published another pamphlet, which still 
 more clearly marked him out as a dangerous man. 
 This work, entitled Labour Defended against the Claims 
 of Capital (1825), claimed to prove that labour was the 
 sole source of wealth, that only producers had any right 
 to a share of the world's wealth, and that in a society 
 thus reconstructed all law must be abolished, as not only 
 useless but harmful. These theories (which curiously 
 foreshadow those of Proudhon and Bakunin) were set 
 forth in small twopenny reprints and formed the chief 
 stock-in-trade of the "unstamped" press of that date.
 
 44 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 The following lines, composed by "one of the know- 
 nothings ", show the working of the popular conscious- 
 ness on the wage-fund theories of Hodgkin and Ricardo: 
 
 "'Wages should form the price of goods'. 
 
 Yes ! Wages should be all : 
 Then we who work to make the goods 
 
 Should justly have them all. 
 But if their price be made of rent, 
 
 Tithes, taxes, profits all, 
 Then we who work to make the goods 
 ' Should have just none at all V 
 
 A study of the inner workings of the people's mind at 
 that period will serve to elucidate many questions which 
 are otherwise difficult to understand. For instance, the 
 extraordinary enthusiasm on behalf of the Reform Bill is 
 hard to account for on the ground merely of a desire for 
 electoral purity; but it becomes intelligible in the light 
 of Mr. Place's assertion, that the bulk of the operatives 
 believed the Bill destined to prepare the way for a redis- 
 tribution of property. Viewed in this light, the Bristol 
 and Nottingham riots might well cause frantic alarm to 
 the propertied classes, which regarded the wanton de- 
 struction there perpetrated as merely a foretaste of mob- 
 rule. Hence also, we may add, the dislike with which 
 even the new reformed government regarded co-opera- 
 tive societies, workmen's political associations, and a 
 cheap press, as alike designed to subvert the framework 
 of society. 
 
 It must be admitted that the action of several of the 
 new Radical clubs seemed 'to justify those fears. The 
 Leeds Radical Union, in Feb. 1832, alarmed the moneyed 
 classes by a declaration that the men who as yet had no 
 votes were not responsible for the national debt, which 
 was the work only of the Whig and Tory factions. 
 Even more ominous was a proposal put forth by a 
 ranting coffee-house keeper of the Strand, named Ben-
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 45 
 
 bow, that the working-classes should strike work for a 
 whole month a Sacred Month dedicated to the claims 
 of labour. In a pamphlet published by him in Jan. 1832 
 he hashed up the arguments of Hodgkin, and proceeded 
 to the practical application that the people ought to 
 seize and divide all property, in case the present owners 
 should not be sufficiently impressed by the Sacred Month 
 to consent to its peaceful redistribution. The pamphlet 
 was embellished by the quotation of many texts of 
 Scripture in justification of this step "The cattle upon 
 a thousand hills are mine " being cited as proof that all 
 oxen might be appropriated by the needy. Eager hopes 
 and fears were aroused by the pamphlet some opera- 
 tives believing that the Sacred Month began when the 
 pamphlet appeared. 
 
 Amidst all this balderdash we can discern some de- 
 mands of a more practical nature. The Radicals of Leeds 
 demanded the repeal of all taxes pressing on the working- 
 classes. The National Union of the Working-classes de- 
 clared that indirect taxation (i.e. taxation on the materials 
 or processes of industry as well as on articles of con- 
 sumption) was a means of upholding monopoly and cor- 
 ruption, and ought to be abolished; whereas graduated 
 taxes on property would compel the rich to refund some 
 of the wealth which their laws had extracted from the 
 poor; that taxation and parliamentary representation 
 ought to be coextensive ; and that those who were ex- 
 cluded from the franchise ought to be free from taxation, 
 and from service in the militia. 
 
 It was clear, however, that these changes could never 
 be brought about until Parliament represented the will 
 of the people of England far more completely than was 
 contemplated in the Whig Reform Bills. Radicals, ac- 
 cordingly, insisted on a drastic reform of the House of 
 Commons, and sought to press on the political clubs to 
 more daring demands than their founders had ever
 
 46 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 formulated. Associations like the Birmingham Political 
 Union had already been framed to support the Whigs 
 against the borough -mongers, and carry Lord John 
 Russell's Reform Bill. But there was some danger of 
 these local clubs and unions falling into the hands of 
 faddists and losing all unity of aim. This was especially 
 the case with the Birmingham Political Union, a power- 
 ful association which threatened to march 100,000 Mid- 
 landers to London to find out why the Reform Bill did 
 not become law. While it was a question of intimidating 
 the Duke of Wellington, the reformers of Birmingham 
 presented a united front; but those who looked beneath 
 the surface saw that the Birmingham leaders were not 
 democrats, but fussy faddists. Chief among them was 
 Thomas Attwood, soon to become known as the first 
 member for Birmingham, and a currency bore of the first 
 magnitude. Attwood was no democrat, and would have 
 induced his union to aim at a 20 limit to the franchise, 
 had not the men of Newcastle and the north declared for 
 the 10 franchise. He valued the Reform Bill chiefly 
 because it gave Birmingham a voice in the nation's 
 councils, and because a little later it sent him to West- 
 minster as one of the two representatives of the Midland 
 capital. This was his long-sought opportunity for striv- 
 ing to re-establish the waning credit of the land, on the 
 basis of an unlimited supply of paper notes. 1 As the 
 men of Birmingham seemed inclined to follow Attwood 
 in his currency craze, while other towns straggled after 
 other local will-o'-the-wisps, some central body was 
 evidently needed to repress provincial fads and bring 
 reformers into line. Place and other Londoners accord- 
 ingly started (October, 1831) a central club, The National 
 Political Union, to give cohesion to the provincial bodies, 
 and unite the middle and labouring classes in common 
 
 1 On this scheme Place remarked, with unusual humour, that it was 
 understood by very few, and was condemned by all who did understand it.
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 47 
 
 political action. The history of this union was to prove 
 how difficult it is to bring- Britons into line, and how 
 impossible to keep them in line. The older reformers, 
 like Sir Thomas Burdett, member for Westminster, 
 speedily took offence at the demand of this union for a 
 "full, free, and effectual representation of the people in 
 the House of Commons", and for the abolition of all 
 "taxes upon knowledge". 
 
 But this programme, far from satisfying all Radicals, 
 far from uniting the middle and working classes in a 
 common aim, was disdainfully flung aside by men who 
 claimed to represent the feelings of the artisans and 
 operatives. As has been already noticed, the disappointed 
 followers of Owen had founded, in April, 1831, a National 
 Union of the Working-classes to prepare, by political 
 action, for that social regeneration which seemed ever to 
 be receding further into the hazy background of the seer's 
 visions. It was in vain that Owen discountenanced 
 political agitation such as his followers now essayed. 
 He had aroused hopes which he could not satisfy, a 
 spirit which he could not control. The ferment caused 
 by the Lords' rejection of the First Reform Bill (Oct., 
 1831) now seemed to the more practical of his followers 
 to promise a speedy overthrow of the old system of 
 society, and with a fervour begotten of their communistic 
 beliefs they sought to drive on the National Political 
 Union to advanced democratic demands. These light 
 skirmishers of the Chartist vanguard had begun to dis- 
 seminate their views in a large hall called the Rotunda, 
 near the Surrey end of Blackfriars Bridge, whence they 
 were known first as the Rotundists, or Rotundanists, 
 according to the speaker's ideas of word-building. There 
 it was that the most important of the "points" of the 
 People's Charter were first popularized. The first sketch 
 of that famous programme, as a fighting creed, is ob- 
 servable in a circular or hand-bill inviting the working-
 
 48 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 men of London to a great meeting on Nov. 7, 1831, in 
 front of White Conduit House. After quoting as mottoes 
 the dicta " Labour is the source of wealth ", and "That 
 commonwealth is the best ordered where the citizens are 
 neither too rich nor too poor ", the circular proceeds to 
 a declaration of rights, which is partly inspired by the 
 Rights of Man of the French revolutionists of 1789: 
 " (i) All property, honestly acquired, is to be sacred and 
 inviolable. (2) All men are born equally free, and have 
 certain natural inherent and inalienable rights. (3) All 
 governments ought to be founded on those rights, and 
 all laws instituted for the common benefit, protection, 
 and security of all the people, and not for the particular 
 emolument or advantage of any single man, family, or 
 set of men. (4) All hereditary distinctions of birth are 
 unnatural, and are opposed to the Equal Rights of Man, 
 and therefore ought to be abolished. (5) Every man of 
 the age of 21 years, who is of sound mind and is not 
 tainted by crime, has a Right, either by himself or by his 
 representative, to a free voice in determining the necessity 
 of public contributions, their appropriation, amount, mode 
 of assessment, and duration. (6) In order to secure the 
 unbiassed choice of proper persons for representatives, 
 the mode of voting should be by ballot ; intellectual fit- 
 ness and moral worth, and not property, should be the 
 qualification for representatives; and the duration of 
 Parliaments should be but for one year." 
 
 It would be tedious to narrate all the disputes between 
 the National Union of the Working-classes and the 
 other union which claimed to combine the aims of the 
 middle and artisan classes in furthering the Whig Reform 
 Bill. Against Lord John Russell's Bill of 1831, and 
 against the slightly amended measure finally passed in 
 June, 1832, Benthamite Radicals and working-men 
 democrats alike protested, the latter declaring that no 
 bill would satisfy them which did not grant universal
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 49 
 
 suffrage, vote by ballot, annual Parliaments, and abo- 
 lition of the property qualification for members of Par- 
 liament. This programme received the adhesion of the 
 Radical clubs of Leeds, Huddersfield, Manchester, Bris- 
 tol and Brighton, though the men of Sussex showed 
 their good sense in substituting "short Parliaments" 
 for "Parliaments annually elected". 1 
 
 Sufficient proof has now been adduced as to the width 
 of the gulf separating working-men Radicals and the 
 Whigs in 1831-1832. Great, indeed, was the disgust of 
 the people when it was found that that child of many 
 hopes, the Act of 1832, still excluded from the franchise 
 those townsfolk who could not pay an annual rental of 
 10, and all save the wealthier leaseholders and copy- 
 holders in rural districts. The redistribution of seats 
 was equally unsatisfactory, Lord John Russell himself 
 subsequently admitting that it had been so manipulated 
 as to yield a permanent majority for the agricultural 
 interest. 
 
 Yet, however keen was the disgust of the more ardent 
 democrats with a measure which admitted to the fran- 
 chise less than half a million of men, that is, less than 
 one-fourth of the number enfranchised by the act of 1884, 
 the momentous character of the Act of 1832 was realized 
 by all keen-sighted observers. They saw that the victory 
 of the reformers upset that balance of power between the 
 three estates of the realm, which had been extolled by 
 Montesquieu as the peculiar virtue of the English con- 
 stitution. After two centuries of equipoise, the balance 
 was now tilted decidedly in favour of the people's House. 
 The majority of Commoners ceased to be nominees of 
 the aristocracy, and became representatives of the middle 
 
 1 It may be noted here that the demand for equal electoral districts was 
 formulated later, and soon disappeared from the Chartist programme ; 
 while that for the payment of members of Parliament originated in the 
 Birmingham Political Union, or rather, was revived by them from Cart- 
 wright's programme of 1780. 
 
 (M416) D
 
 50 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 classes; and when the representative system was ad- 
 mitted to form the basis of the House of Commons, it 
 was inevitable that further changes should follow the 
 course of the new industrial developments of our land. 
 Further than this, the means of effecting- such changes 
 had been discovered. The arcana of state-craft had been 
 divulged, never again to be concealed under the trappings 
 of an almost mediaeval past. The coercion applied by 
 the masses of the people to the wavering monarch had 
 induced him to warn the recalcitrant Lords that unless 
 they passed the bill, their opposition would be swamped 
 by a wholesale nomination of new peers. The sur- 
 render of the Upper House revealed the hitherto secret 
 machinery of our constitutional life, and proved how 
 irresistible was the pressure of the popular demand both 
 on the monarchy and the aristocracy. The prerogative 
 of the crown was thenceforth a lever which could be 
 wielded for the overthrow of aristocratic power ; and the 
 House which could set that force to work was naturally 
 supreme in the state. Since 1832 the efforts of democrats 
 have accordingly been directed, not against the monarch 
 or the Lords, but to the acquisition of completer control 
 over the House of Commons. This is a fact of the 
 utmost importance, as it marks off English Radicalism 
 from the cognate democratic movements on the Con- 
 tinent, which, unable to effect a lodgment in existing 
 institutions, have generally striven to overturn them. 
 They have been revolutionary: our Radicalism has in 
 the main been evolutionary. 
 
 It is a profound remark of the Roman historian, Tacitus, 
 that the obedience of a people may be gravely suspected 
 when they prefer to interpret rather than to follow the 
 commands of their rulers. What would he have said 
 to a state of things where the ruler has to interpret the 
 wishes of his people? Yet that has been the anomalous 
 position of the crown since 1832. The importance of
 
 Radicals and the Reform Bill of 1832. 51 
 
 the change has been obscured partly by our innate 
 respect for constitutional forms, partly by the surprising- 
 adaptability of our rulers and our parties to new con- 
 ditions. Subsequently I shall have to dilate on these 
 features of our political life which tend to peace and 
 stability. Here I may merely note that the results of 
 the Reform Bill of 1832 were discounted by the personal 
 ascendency of Earl Grey, and of Lords Melbourne and 
 Palmerston, in the ranks of the reformers; so that not 
 until the death of the last, in 1865, did the full conse- 
 quences of the measure develop themselves. On the 
 other hand, the beaten Tory party, under the able lead 
 of Sir Robert Peel, began to reorganize itself with a view 
 to the new requirements of the age, and speedily emerged 
 from obscurity with renewed vigour and vitality. These 
 and other causes conspired to postpone the triumph of 
 Radical agitation for well-nigh forty years. 
 
 An assertion has therefore found favour that the Act 
 of 1832 was conservative rather than progressive, that 
 it closed an old epoch rather than inaugurated a new 
 one. Certainly, in the restoration of the franchise to 
 something like its old character, and in the averting of 
 civil war or revolution, the measure may in the best 
 sense be called conservative ; and if this elastic term may 
 also be used to denote a series of changes which have 
 ultimately led to the transfer of almost complete power 
 to the middle and working classes, then the same appel- 
 lation may be justified. But, on the other hand, the 
 reform struggle of 1831-1832 was to prove a stimulus 
 to democratic agitation by revealing the predominance 
 of the Commons over the other two estates of the realm, 
 and by showing how that power could be increased. 
 Lord Bacon remarks that a government is wise when it 
 handles things in such a way as to leave to the discon- 
 tented "some outlet of hope". That was the condition 
 of things in the early part of the Victorian era. Amidst
 
 52 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 all the distress of those years, the hope of gaining a 
 fuller control over the People's House was the pole-star 
 of the moral -force Chartists and their sympathizers, 
 guiding them in the channel of constitutional agitation, 
 and away from the rocks and shoals of forceful intrigue. 
 In its immediate effects, then, the great Reform Act 
 of 1832 may be called conservative; while its wider and 
 ultimate result was to further the progress of democracy 
 by characteristically English methods. It is the chief 
 glory of our race that, while stiff and unyielding as 
 individuals, it is in the mass surprisingly adaptable to 
 new political circumstances. In the majestic cycle of 
 growth from Alfred the Great to Victoria, no episode 
 illustrates more clearly than the struggle for reform our 
 deeply-rooted instinct to cling to the old and adapt it to 
 new conditions as they arise. It is this which has im- 
 parted to the English constitution its unique powers of 
 juvenescence, and has dowered the Victorian era with 
 its faculty of many-sided yet peaceful expansion. 
 
 Chapter III. 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law. 
 
 With the general policy of the reformed Parliament 
 we have here no concern, not even for its noble 
 generosity in according ^"20,000,000 to colonial planters 
 as the price of their slaves' emancipation. Our task is 
 rather to trace the growth of popular feeling on questions 
 which the Whig ministry failed satisfactorily to solve, 
 and to watch the dissolution of the temporary and 
 artificial alliance between Whigs and Radicals which 
 carried the Act of 1832. 
 
 That measure installed the middle classes in power;
 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law. 53 
 
 and the artisan class waited to see how that power 
 would be used. A collision of interests soon became 
 inevitable amidst the problems produced by the indus- 
 trial changes of the time. The questions most closely 
 affecting the wage-earners were the organization of 
 trade-unions to resist frequent reductions of wages, and 
 the protection by legal recognition and control of the 
 co-operative societies which the more practical followers 
 of Robert Owen had endeavoured to conduct. On both 
 these topics the attitude of the Whig ministry was 
 disappointingly passive, if not actually hostile. Ministers 
 could not oppose the formation of numerous trade- 
 unions, seeing that in 1825 the old laws forbidding 
 their formation had been repealed. Still, they and their 
 supporters viewed with apprehension the organization of 
 the working-classes, which were deeply imbued with the 
 levelling theories of Owen and Hodgkin ; and when, after 
 nearly all industries had been organized, trade-unionism 
 began to spread among agricultural labourers, the 
 authorities took alarm. There were certainly some 
 grounds for apprehension. In and after the year 1829 
 many bands of peasants had marched from village to 
 village under the orders of an imaginary leader called 
 "Swing", burning ricks, smashing the hated machinery, 
 and threatening agriculture with ruin. After a temporary 
 abatement of this violence, it now seemed to be about to 
 revive in an organized form by the formation of a Grand 
 National Union, which urged agricultural labourers not 
 to work for less than ten shillings a week. As this 
 pittance was rarely obtained by the labourers of Dorset, 
 some earnest men of Tolpuddle, near Dorchester, formed 
 a "grand lodge" in their village, and ordered of the 
 village painter a figure of Death of heroic stature in 
 order duly to impress the future members. Scared by 
 this portent, the farmers set the law in motion, with the 
 result that the magistrates, and finally the judge, under
 
 54 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 an antiquated statute, convicted the leaders of enrolling 
 men by oath. For this offence, in spite of their admitted 
 good character, they were sentenced to seven years' 
 transportation (1834); and were only tardily rescued 
 from Botany Bay by the indignant protests of vast 
 meetings of their countrymen. Little more need be 
 said on the subject of trade-unionism here, except 
 that it was a powerful feeder of political discontent, 
 and was soon to show its power amidst the strikes of 
 1842. 
 
 The Whig- ministry was equally unfriendly to the 
 growth of the co-operative movement, believing, and 
 not unreasonably, that under the guise of co-operation 
 the Owenites were desirous of furthering their com- 
 munistic schemes. All that the more level-headed 
 followers of the New Lanark seer really desired was 
 legal protection for the new co-operative societies 
 against the designs of fraudulent officers, whose flight 
 with all the available cash brought many a store to 
 collapse and thousands of families to beggary. Up to 
 the year 1846 neither co-operative nor benefit societies 
 received any recognition at law, much less any super- 
 vision such as would diminish the risks of fraud. Not 
 till that year was any measure passed by Parliament 
 on the subject. The feeling of government towards 
 the early co-operators was one of suspicion and dislike, 
 which they repaid with interest. 
 
 In all probability, however, Radicals would have 
 found no general support, and the People's Charter 
 would never have been drawn up, but for the blaze of 
 discontent caused by the exorbitant stamp duty on 
 newspapers and by the severity of the new Poor-law of 
 1834. This law was passed at a time when the collapse 
 of the federated trade-unions and of many co-operative 
 societies revealed the impotence of the wage-earners for 
 sustained and well-organized action. Old questions and
 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law, 55 
 
 old agitators were passing- away. 1 The agitation for 
 factory reform, championed by Lord Ashley (afterwards 
 Lord Shaftesbury) and Mr. Fielden, member for Oldham, 
 had already brought industrial and social questions to 
 the fore; and now the drastic Poor-law of 1834 con- 
 centrated the attention of prince and peasant, rate-payer 
 and pauper, on the pressing problem of poor-relief. It 
 was a sign of the times when the veteran agitator Cob- 
 bett, and the foppish "Tory-Radical", Benjamin Disraeli, 
 joined hands to oppose the passing of the Whig measure 
 of 1834. 
 
 The evils of our older system of relief of the poor, 
 with which the reform ministry had to grapple, cer- 
 tainly called for energetic action. Some of them may 
 be traced back to the famous law of Queen Elizabeth, 
 which first strove to alleviate the distress caused by the 
 many social changes of the Tudor period. That measure 
 charged the authorities of each parish to maintain their 
 own destitute persons; but the merely parochial cha- 
 racter of the system early produced diversities in the 
 management which made it necessary to fence off the 
 poor of one parish from the poor of another parish. 
 Various Acts of Settlement were passed, which rendered 
 it increasingly difficult for a rural labourer to gain a 
 legal settlement in any but his native parish. Indeed 
 Adam Smith, the author of the immortal work The 
 Wealth of Nations (1776), satirically remarked that the 
 English peasant had to stay where he was born and 
 bred, lest he might perchance become a burden to the 
 poor-rates of some other parish. A few efforts were 
 made to remedy the harshness of the Law of Settle- 
 
 1 The rancorous diatribes of the older agitators, Hunt and Cobbett, against 
 all men in authority and against one another, were losing them their 
 earlier influence with the masses ; and Hunt received notice from his con- 
 stituents at Preston that they would not again require his services in Parlia- 
 ment. Hunt and Cobbett were both in the last year of their feverish 
 existence.
 
 56 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 ment; but they had little effect; and our villages re- 
 mained almost as isolated as in the middle ages. 
 
 Customs so cramping to the life of our rural poor 
 naturally subjected them to a terrible strain during times 
 of scarcity, such as those of the long war with France. 
 The system practically broke down; but the parochial 
 authorities, instead of demanding the abolition of the 
 Law of Settlement, so that their surplus poor might go 
 away freely to the new factory towns where work was 
 to be had, took the unwise step of doling out relief from 
 the rates in proportion to the price of bread and to the 
 number of children in the family relieved. This practice, 
 for which we are indebted to the sagacity of the magi- 
 strates of Speenhamland in Berkshire, was adopted by 
 hundreds of parishes which saw no other way out of 
 present difficulties. The natural results speedily fol- 
 lowed: habits of prudence, foresight, and self-restraint 
 were at a discount; and a labouring man, waxing fat 
 and flourishing according to the number of children 
 clustering thick about him, could repeat with gusto 
 the benediction of the Psalmist on the man who had 
 his quiver full of them. Rale-payers, however, were 
 increasingly inclined to doubt the applicability of the 
 blessing to an over-populated island, and gave willing 
 ear to the protests of the Rev. Dr. Malthus against 
 methods of poor-relief which threatened to deluge us 
 with a generation of bounty-bred and bounty-fed paupers. 
 Fortunately, the customs first adopted in 1796 did not 
 spread to most of the parishes of the north and the far 
 west a fact which probably accounts for the greater 
 independence of the working-classes in those parts ; but 
 even there the prospects of weekly doles from the parish 
 were beginning to lead to acts of intimidation with a 
 view to compelling magistrates to adopt the customs of 
 the south. In the southern and south-midland districts 
 nearly every rural parish had adopted the system, with
 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law. 57 
 
 the result that the village poorhouse was crowded with 
 demoralized creatures, who lived lavishly at the expense 
 of their more independent neighbours. Farmers often 
 turned off their labourers, and took them on at two- 
 thirds of their former wages, knowing that the parish 
 would make up the wages to the total amount required 
 by the price of corn and the size of the several families. 
 To rate-payers who could not adopt similar dodges the 
 system spelt ruin, unless they too went on the parish a 
 process adopted in one village of Buckinghamshire with 
 such gratifying success that every parishioner except 
 the parson became a pauper. The system was twice 
 cursed : it cursed those who paid rates by impoverishing 
 them ; it cursed those who received by debasing them. 
 
 The experience of practical men and the ideas of politi- 
 cal economists alike condemned these insensate customs. 
 Indeed, the activity in economic thought aroused by the 
 Essay on Population of the Rev. Dr. Malthus, may be 
 considered as largely resulting from the problem of 
 pauperism, which that amiable clergyman endeavoured 
 to explain and solve. All the circumstances of the time 
 favoured the supremacy of the principle of laisserfaire, or 
 non-interference with individual liberty, as the best safe- 
 guard of private and public prosperity. The economist 
 Ricardo emphasized the inexorable action of economic 
 law. The futility of state intervention was set forth in 
 many other writings; and no topic afforded so triumphant 
 an illustration of these arguments as the abuses of a 
 poor-law system which was pauperizing well-nigh half 
 the nation. Clever writers like the Rev. Sydney Smith 
 and Miss Martineau demonstrated the need for a com- 
 plete change, if not the abolition of the Poor-law. But 
 the Tory cabinets of 1815-1830 were paralysed by that 
 timidity which has beset every non-representative gov- 
 ernment of this century when confronted by wide-spread 
 misery or disaffection. With the Whig government of
 
 58 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 1832 the new political economy leaped to power, at 
 least as regards all questions which did not injure the 
 interests of the parliamentary majority, and it was there- 
 fore left to the Whig government of the middle classes 
 and doctrinaire philosophers to cleanse the Augean stable 
 of pauperism. A commission was appointed in 1833 to 
 report on the evils above-described; and the Poor-law 
 Amendment Act of 1834 embodied nearly all the recom- 
 mendations of the commission. Its chief provisions 
 may be thus summarized: (i) The government of the 
 United Kingdom for the first time gained definite and 
 almost complete control of the system of poor-relief, 
 thus reducing parochial customs of relief to comparative 
 uniformity and rendering impossible any intimidation by 
 village ruffians. (2) Instead of each parish managing its 
 own poorhouse, parishes were to be grouped together 
 in a larger district called a union, having one work- 
 house. Each union workhouse was to be controlled by 
 rate-payers, under supervision from a new governmental 
 body sitting in London, the Poor-law Board. 1 (3) The 
 system of doles from the rates in aid of wages was 
 entirely swept away, by out-door relief being prohibited 
 to all able-bodied persons. (4) The old Law of Settle- 
 ment was so far modified as to make it easy for a 
 labouring man to migrate in search of work. We may 
 note in passing that labour hereby gained a fluidity un- 
 known in England for fully two centuries. The new 
 railways were soon to aid in the transference of popula- 
 tion from congested villages to manufacturing districts, 
 to the great advantage of rural rate-payers, but to the 
 harm of factory artisans, whose wages were severely 
 depressed by the inflowing tide of unskilled labour. 
 
 The act passed the Commons almost unanimously, 
 only twenty members following Cobbett in his headlong 
 opposition ; and in the view of the rate-payers, the mea- 
 1 It now is merged in the Local Government Board.
 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law. 59 
 
 sure "saved the country". Many of its provisions were 
 indeed most salutory, restoring' to the English labourer 
 his earlier habits of thrift and independence ; while the 
 freer movement of labourers tended to break up the foul 
 nests of corruption into which our villages had often 
 degenerated. 
 
 And yet there was some reason in the opposition 
 which Cobbett, the young Disraeli, and the Times news- 
 paper alike offered to the measure. The support vigor- 
 ously accorded by the cantankerous Lord Brougham 
 sufficed to ensure its unpopularity, especially when he 
 asserted that the mere fact of a man's destitution proved 
 that Nature had no room for him "at her already over- 
 crowded table". Besides, the measure applied almost 
 indiscriminately the same remedy to urban and rural, 
 manufacturing and agricultural districts. It offered the 
 first prominent example of a wholesale application of 
 laisser-faire principles to destitute persons whose con- 
 ditions of life differed in nearly every respect. 1 More- 
 over, the transition was in most cases made with very 
 little previous notice, and certainly with none of the 
 needful preliminary training in thrift. People who for 
 more than a generation had grown accustomed for the 
 parish to "find them in everything", were suddenly told 
 that they must thenceforth shift for themselves, or go 
 into the new grim workhouses, there to be separated, to 
 don the paupers' garb, and subsist on bread of affliction 
 and water of affliction. The change, after the old 
 liberal rations of meat and beer, was certainly trying. 
 If it was true that under the old system new-comers at 
 the Reading workhouse had been upset by the high 
 living, was it not also true that in every workhouse after 
 1834, paupers were being worn to the bone by the hard 
 
 1 Still more extraordinary was the application (1838) of the new poor-law 
 to Ireland, where there had been no poor-law at all, and where out-door 
 relief was to be entirely prohibited I The law was extended to Scotland in 
 1845.
 
 60 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 work and meagre fare now administered to them? 
 There is abundant evidence (quite apart from Oliver 
 T-wfst^} that the change was so sudden and acute as to 
 provoke the wrath of the honest labouring poor. For- 
 tunately it occurred at a time when wheat was unusually 
 plentiful and cheap, the average price in the years 
 1834-36 being only 43^. the quarter. But when from 1837 
 years of scarcity followed one another in dreary succes- 
 sion, labourers began to rage against the authors of the 
 poor-law reform who had placed before them the cruel 
 alternative of complete independence or the workhouse. 
 The report of the select parliamentary committee, 
 which inquired into the working of the new law, in- 
 cludes several hostile petitions, those from Lancashire 
 being especially vigorous. The men of Salford and 
 Oldham protested in almost identical terms that, as the 
 poor had indisputable right to a maintenance in exchange 
 for their labour, they were filled with dismay at the in- 
 troduction of the new law; by which "men have been 
 forcibly and illegally separated from their wives, and 
 both of them from their children, and have been confined 
 in separate cells in large prisons called Union work- 
 houses, clad in prison dresses, and reduced by insufficient 
 coarse food to the confines of starvation ". Lancashire 
 had been free from the worst evils of the old system. It 
 was natural, then, that the County Palatine, together 
 with other populous districts of the north, should resent 
 the severities of the new poor-law; and that the bulk 
 of the "testimonials" in its favour should come from 
 the south midland and southern counties which it 
 rescued from impending financial ruin. At all events, 
 the evidence points clearly to the fact that, though the 
 
 1 Dickens possibly borrowed his story of Oliver Twist asking for " more" 
 from a caricaturing song of the period, which described how a boy on asking 
 for more soup was pitched by the master of the workhouse into the copper, 
 there to serve as " stock " for the enrichment of the liquid !
 
 The Revolt against the New Poor-law. 61 
 
 new law was hailed with gratitude by the rate-payers of 
 the south, it moved the indignation of the workers in 
 our great industrial centres. If further evidence is 
 needed as to the hatred caused by the new law, it may 
 be found at Leicester, where, at the general election of 
 1841, the cry was raised " Let us end the power of the 
 Whigs. Vote for the Tories in preference to the Whigs, 
 the authors of the accursed Poor-law ". 
 
 There was some reason in these feelings of resent- 
 ment. Artisans felt that the Whig government had 
 cheated their sturdiest supporters, the men whose en- 
 thusiasm in the cause of parliamentary reform had 
 broken down the close ring of the borough-mongers : it 
 was their voices which had swelled the cry of "The 
 bill, the whole bill, and nothing but the bill": it was 
 their persistent toil which had given to that movement 
 its irresistible momentum, and had placed the Whigs 
 securely in power. And what had been their reward? 
 The first great measure of domestic concern had been 
 this Poor-law Act, which cut down the rates, but by 
 means of poor-law Bastilles and a diet of skilly for the 
 destitute. To the suspicious imaginations of working- 
 men the Municipal Reform Act of 1835 appeared to be 
 merely another middle-class measure; for had not the 
 reformed House of Commons accepted with little modi- 
 fication the Lords' amendment, and thereby excluded 
 from the elective town-councils all councillors who did 
 not possess a certain amount of real or personal pro- 
 perty? 
 
 As the legislation of 1833-1837 was wholly in favour 
 of the newly enfranchised middle-classes, would not a 
 genuinely democratic Parliament right the wrongs of 
 the artisans and rural labourers? This was the feeling 
 fermenting in myriads of brains. These were the events 
 which broke up the alliance between Whigs and Radi- 
 cals, and the schism tended, at least on all industrial
 
 6a The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 questions, to ally Whigs and Tories in a solid phalanx 
 against change; while very many of the working-men, 
 when left without any cultured leaders, fell under the 
 influence of men who advocated physical force. 
 
 If, as will be shown in the next chapter, "moral- 
 force " Chartism was largely the outcome of the agita- 
 tion for a free press, "physical-force" Chartism gained 
 its strength from the popular hatred against the new 
 poor-law Bastilles, a hatred fanned almost into a 
 flame of revolt by the rabid rhetoric of Stephens and 
 Oastler in the north. 
 
 Chapter IV. 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 
 
 Before proceeding to a description of the Chartist 
 movement, it may be well to diverge from the beaten 
 track of politics to describe a struggle which has had 
 an incalculable influence on modern life. In these days 
 of cheap daily newspapers it seems scarcely credible 
 that up to 1836 the average price of an English journal 
 was sevenpence, and that frugal and law-abiding folk 
 rarely indulged in that costly luxury except on Saturday 
 or Sunday. The high price of papers was caused partly, 
 of course, by the comparatively small numbers who in 
 any one district were able to take an intelligent interest 
 in public affairs. The iron horse had not as yet acceler- 
 ated the distribution of newspapers. The citizen of 
 Leicester or Oxford never dreamt then of a day when 
 the London daily paper should be on his breakfast-table. 
 The day of the engineer had not yet fully dawned. The 
 hand of the man of law was still heavy on the land, and 
 the popular intelligence slumbered under the pressure
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 63 
 
 of laws which seemed designed to postpone the awaken- 
 ing to a distant future. The miserable sum of ^20,000 
 was in and after 1833 annually doled out by govern- 
 ment in aid of the education which some noble men and 
 women were endeavouring to extend to their benighted 
 countrymen; and this sum was less than a fiftieth part 
 of what our administrators then raised by the "taxes 
 on knowledge". 
 
 These odious taxes included the stamp duty of four- 
 pence on every copy of a newspaper, the duty of three- 
 pence on every pound of paper, and a heavy impost on 
 advertisements. It would be difficult to say whether 
 these taxes were imposed with the aim of helping the 
 revenue, or, as was claimed by Dr. Birkbeck in 1835, 
 to check the growth of popular intelligence. A good 
 case could be made out for either supposition. On the 
 one hand, it might fairly be urged that these, or similar 
 taxes, were rendered necessary by the refusal of the 
 House of Commons in 1815 to impose any longer on the 
 propertied classes the crushing impost of two shillings 
 in the pound on income, which they had gallantly borne 
 for the last nine years of the war. Hence the govern- 
 ment was forced to recur to the system of placing heavy 
 duties on multifarious articles, until the Rev. Sydney 
 Smith could say, with equal wit and truth, that every 
 article was taxed, from the top of the schoolboy to the 
 medicine which ended the old man's days and the marble 
 which recorded his virtues. It was only natural, then, 
 that the newspaper press should speedily be subjected 
 to a stamp duty of fourpence per copy, and that paper 
 and advertisements should also be taxed. 
 
 Undoubtedly, however, the growth of ribald and 
 seditious pamphlets amidst the distress and discontent 
 of 1815 strengthened the determination of the govern- 
 ment to impose these heavy taxes on knowledge. But, 
 so far from repressing sedition, the increased newspaper
 
 64 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 tax proved to be its best feeder. The poor or econo- 
 mical, being unable to afford the ninepenny Times, 
 Morning Chronicle, or Herald, betook themselves to 
 cheap publications like those of Cobbett, which, under 
 the guise of a weekly letter, evaded the duty; and the 
 success of his Twopenny Register raised up a number of 
 unstamped papers which indulged in the most violent 
 and scurrilous abuse of the Regent, the Castlereagh 
 ministry, the church, and all the institutions of the land. 
 In order to suppress these seditious and abusive prints, 
 Castlereagh introduced and passed an act for the purpose 
 of stopping their production and sale, with the natural 
 result that the severe penalties imposed exasperated the 
 democrats and increased the number of their pamphlets 
 and prints. 
 
 The tax on paper was equally serious, for it rendered 
 difficult, if not impossible, the publication of cheap 
 literature. An example of this is seen in the praise- 
 worthy attempt made by Mr. Charles Knight to spread 
 enlightenment by his Penny Encyclopaedia. The com- 
 pletion of this truly great and noble work entailed on 
 him a total loss of ^32,000, and of this deficit ^30,000 
 was caused by the heavy duty on paper. In one of her 
 tales illustrative of political economy, Miss Martineau 
 stated that there were in the United Kingdom nearly 
 800 paper-mills, producing paper which was valued at 
 ;i, 500,000; and the paper-duty amounted to as much 
 as ^770,000, or far more than the wages of the 25,000 
 workmen employed. The means taken by government 
 to prevent any evasion of this tax may be illustrated by 
 an incident which befell William Lovett, whose career 
 will presently be described. After the visit of an old 
 farmer-like gentleman to the co-operative association of 
 which Lovett was secretary, there came a writ from 
 Somerset House charging him with defrauding the 
 revenue. After long search and laborious inquiry at the
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 65 
 
 official "circumlocution office", the offence was found 
 to consist in the co-operative quarterly report, which 
 contained one quarter of a printer's sheet of paper on 
 which the duty of one shilling- had not been paid a fact 
 noticed by the government spy, who had come in the 
 guise of a friend from the country desirous of spreading- 
 the blessings of co-operation in his native village. 
 
 When books and pamphlets were subjected to this 
 vexatious impost, and newspapers were rendered a 
 costly luxury, it was natural that all friends of the people 
 should combine in an effort to sweep away all these 
 obnoxious "taxes on knowledge". The benevolent Dr. 
 Birkbeck, whose Institution had lately commenced its 
 grand work of educating the youth of the metropolis, 
 and Mr. Chadwick, the pioneer in so many social re- 
 forms, were the first to initiate a public agitation on the 
 subject, in a meeting held at the City of London Scientific 
 and Literary Institution, in April, 1830. The excite- 
 ment aroused by the revolutions on the Continent and 
 the reform struggle in our own land gave a further 
 impulse to the growth of an "unstamped" press, by 
 which working-men leaders determined, in defiance of 
 the law, to diffuse political information among their own 
 class at a popular price. In this determination lay the 
 germ of the cheap newspaper press of to-day, with its 
 multifarious powers. 
 
 At the outset of the struggle, the champions of popular 
 intelligence had no doubts whatever as to the wholly 
 beneficent influence of their new creation. Witness 
 this poem of Ebenezer Elliott, the "Corn Law Rhymer" 
 of Sheffield, in which, after singing of the creation of 
 light, he concludes : 
 
 "And shall the mortal sons of God 
 Be senseless as the trodden clod 
 And darker than the tomb? 
 No, by the mind of man, 
 
 (M416) E
 
 66 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 By the swart artisan, 
 
 By God, our Sire 1 
 Our souls have holy light within, 
 And every form of grief and sin 
 
 Shall see and feel its fire." 
 
 "'The Press', all lands shall sing 
 The Press, the Press we bring 
 
 All lands to bless. 
 Oh, pallid want, oh, labour stark, 
 Behold, we bring the second ark ! 
 
 The Press! The Press! The Press!" 
 
 The new faith was speedily to find its champions and 
 martyrs. To the working-men who were to form the 
 backbone of moral-force Chartism, political enfranchise- 
 ment never seemed an end in itself, but rather a means 
 of gaining opportunities of social, mental, and moral 
 improvement. This was the motive force which im- 
 pelled men like William Lovett, Henry Vincent, and 
 Hetherington through their varied toils and imprison- 
 ments. A brief sketch of these men may not be out of 
 place here ; for by them and others of their class move- 
 ments were initiated which were later on to be patronized, 
 and finally adopted, by responsible statesmen. 
 
 William Lovett, the future compiler of the People's 
 Charter, was born in 1800 at the fishing village of 
 Newlyn, in Cornwall, shortly after the death of his father 
 at sea. His boyhood, passed amidst the delights of the 
 sea-shore, the privations caused by the war, and the 
 alarms excited by the press-gang, naturally aroused in 
 his gifted and sensitive being a love of nature and 
 indignation at the wrongs inflicted by man. Necessity 
 soon drove the lad to London, where he arrived with 
 little money and no friend. In his lodgings in South- 
 wark he was alike surprised and disgusted at the filth of 
 the tenements and the rowdy behaviour of the inhabi-
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 67 
 
 tants. Blackened eyes were especially common on the 
 Monday as a result of the previous days' " sprees", and 
 prize fights not infrequently went on in the streets almost 
 unchecked by the feeble and ill-organized watchmen. 
 Though for a time almost on the verge of starvation, 
 Lovett, by industry and (thrift, ultimately raised himself 
 above these degraded surroundings, being helped in his 
 struggles by attendance at the classes of Dr. Birkbeck's 
 Institute. The success of his teachers in imparting 
 technical knowledge, and in awakening the mental and 
 moral faculties, was in Lovett's case so complete that 
 he often dined on bread and cheese that he might add 
 to his scanty store of books. 1 His eager desire for the 
 improvement of his fellows led him to start the move- 
 ment for opening museums on Sundays, with a petition 
 which set forth the growth of intemperance consequent 
 on the want of rational recreation. 
 
 But Lovett's work was to be mainly political. Along 
 with very many self-educated men of those days, he came 
 under the spell of Robert Owen's ideas for the renovation 
 of society, which have been previously described; but 
 the young Cornishman, with all the imaginative qualities 
 of his race, had a keen regard for practical results, to 
 which Owen's schemes could with the utmost difficulty 
 be adapted. When, therefore, the seer was laying down 
 the laws for his new society at New Harmony in the 
 United States, Lovett and some other half-convinced 
 Owenites started co-operative stores, in order to bring 
 the system into touch with the workaday world. He 
 became the secretary of the central co-operative society, 
 
 J The foundation by Mr. Brougham of " The Society for the Diffusion of 
 Useful Knowledge" in 1825, was beginning to place good books and maga- 
 zines within the reach of many an artisan who previously had had only 
 Cobbett's Register or the frequently ribald productions of the " unstamped" 
 press. To counteract these vicious influences the new society issued the 
 Penny Magazine, which as was asserted by the then Lord Brougham in 
 1834 speedily extinguished the worst of those publications.
 
 68 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 called "The British Association for Promoting Co-opera- 
 tive Knowledge"; and not even the failure of this and 
 many other co-operative societies quenched his belief in 
 the future success of this principle, which was to be 
 realized ten years later by the Rochdale Pioneers. De- 
 spite the collapse of this association, Lovett, with un- 
 daunted energy, organized, in April, 1831, the National 
 Union of the Working-classes, which vainly strove to 
 carry a truly democratic reform. On the decline of this 
 association, Hetherington and he founded the London 
 Working-men's Association (1836), with the aim of im- 
 proving the moral and mental position of their fellows, 
 and of gaining further political rights. The repeal of 
 the crushing tax on newspapers occupied their energies 
 at the outset; and no part of Lovett's life was more 
 fruitful in results than the efforts which he and his 
 associates made for popularizing knowledge and political 
 instruction. 
 
 Throughout the turmoil of strifes which besmirched 
 many a reputation, Lovett's character and career stood 
 forth firm, manly, and consistent. Nature had not 
 bestowed on him physical force sufficient to stand the 
 strain of an active mind and a nervous temperament 
 when placed amidst sordid and chafing surroundings. 
 But though "soured by the perplexities of life", and 
 weighted by a delicate frame, he never hesitated to 
 stand forth in defence of his principles, defying alike 
 tyrants and demagogues. In 1831 he allowed his 
 furniture to be seized and sold rather than serve in 
 the militia, for which he had been drawn. Eight years 
 later, with equal staunchness he signed a Chartist pro- 
 test, knowing well that it would lodge him in Warwick 
 jail. As a rule his speeches were distinguished for 
 reasonableness and manly independence; but, when 
 excited by any act of injustice, his usually mild intel- 
 lectual features were lit up by the fierce fires that burnt
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 69 
 
 within, and his speech rang- with indignation. And yet 
 he never became a firebrand; for, realizing from his 
 early teacher Owen the futility of mere brute force and 
 the more lasting effects of moral suasion, he always 
 sought to convince rather than to coerce; and, risking 
 the loss ot popularity, he never shrank from exposing 
 the folly of those physical -force Chartists who were 
 swayed by the gusts of popular applause and passion. 
 If in addition to his many estimable qualities nature had 
 bestowed on him that force of character which dominates 
 men and affairs, the Chartist movement might have 
 gained a speedier and completer success than it was to 
 achieve. As it is, he left behind him the record of a 
 long life unceasingly devoted to the moral and political 
 advancement of his class, and far more influential than 
 that of many of the so-called statesmen of his time. 
 
 Henry Vincent was another proof of the justice of 
 Kingsley's remark that the Chartist movement called 
 forth the energies of all our best working-men. The 
 future famous lecturer was born in High Holborn in 
 1813; but his father soon removed to Hull, where the 
 boy was apprenticed to a printer. The political excite- 
 ments of 1830 first drew the lad into the whirl of public 
 affairs; and after the return of the family to London 
 young Vincent's oratorical powers gained him increasing 
 popularity with the Radicals who were wont to gather 
 to applaud their favourite speakers in Clerkenwell Green. 
 Like other young democrats of those days, he joined 
 in the work of circulating the cheap unstamped news- 
 papers; and extending his work to the provinces, he 
 became a contributor, and later, an editor, of the un- 
 stamped Western Vindicator, published at Bath. Vin- 
 cent's florid writing and his passionate rhetoric were 
 well suited to the ardent west -country temperament. 
 His mobile features, the magic of his voice, and his 
 impassioned perorations, produced an extraordinary
 
 70 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 effect, perhaps unequalled since the time when Whit- 
 field's thrilling- appeals drew tears to the grimy cheeks 
 of the Gloucestershire miners. Political passion, a 
 century later, now made Vincent's oratory a danger 
 among the excitable miners of Monmouthshire, who, 
 as we shall presently see, marched in thousands to 
 rescue him from the jail at Newport where the fears of 
 the propertied classes had immured him. Vincent's 
 charm of manner and his claim for the complete political 
 equality of the sexes gained him unique popularity with 
 the women of the west, as was seen in a great demon- 
 stration in his honour given by them at Hartshill Gar- 
 dens, Bath, from which every other man was excluded. 
 Apart from its ludicrous aspects, this event is noteworthy 
 as marking the progress of the Women's Rights move- 
 ment, of which John Stuart Mill was the intellectual 
 champion, and as tending to range the early female 
 emancipators shoulder to shoulder with the champions 
 of the unstamped press and of the Charter. Of Henry 
 Vincent's career subsequent to his imprisonment we 
 need say little more. The editing of his newspaper, 
 platform speaking, election contests, and lectures on 
 historical and moral subjects filled up an energetic and 
 useful life. Long before its close, in 1878, he had the 
 gratification of seeing the last of the ' ' taxes on know- 
 ledge " repealed, while most of his political aims had 
 also been realized. Indeed, few men have exercised a 
 more stimulating influence than Vincent on the middle 
 and working classes of his time, first by his political 
 orations, and later by his lectures. Popular lecturing 
 on moral and historical subjects was hardly known 
 until Vincent revealed its potentialities. His power 
 both as a speaker and lecturer lay not in argument, in 
 which he was admittedly very deficient, but rather in 
 the glow of fancy and exuberance of language in which 
 he suffused his subject, and in the dramatic peroration,
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 71 
 
 which, as I have been assured by one of his numerous 
 admirers, frequently brought a whole audience to its 
 feet. 1 
 
 For the more virile advocacy of a free press we must 
 turn to Henry Hetherington and John Cleave. The 
 former was born in London in 1792, and was brought 
 up to the printing trade. After the war period, becom- 
 ing imbued with Robert Owen's doctrines, he threw all 
 his energies into the cause of co-operation and demo- 
 cratic reform. Though endowed with less organizing 
 and tactical skill than Lovett, and less rhetorical power 
 than Vincent, Hetherington was a man of greater re- 
 source, reasoning ability, and will power. In order to 
 effect the equalization of wealth, he determined to defy 
 Castlereagh's press law and issue unstamped weekly 
 Penny Papers for the People (Oct. 1830), changing the 
 title at the end of the year to " The Poor Man's 
 Guardian, established contrary to law to try the power 
 of right against might ". At the corner where the 
 government stamp should have come, appeared the 
 motto " Knowledge is Power", around a printing-press. 
 In its little space of four pages this prototype of the 
 cheap press in England included scanty scraps of news, 
 two or three advertisements of Radical or freethought 
 pamphlets, and a long article filled with violent abuse 
 of the Whig and Tory factions. Throughout the reform 
 struggle, Hetherington declaimed against the "apostasy 
 and villainy of the Whigs ", and against Parliament, 
 which he dubbed the "Westminster tax-trap". Mon- 
 archy was "an expensive farce which ought at once to 
 be closed"; the standing army of "man-butchers" 
 ought speedily to be disbanded, and the sponge be 
 applied to the debt "called national". One short and 
 bloody struggle would gain all these boons and end 
 the inequalities of wealth. As respectable booksellers 
 1 See also Solly's These Eighty Years, vol. i. chap. 12,
 
 72 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 shrank from the risk of vending this illegal print, 
 Hetherington gathered a band of volunteers to sell it 
 in the streets or hawk it from house to house. He and 
 his news-agents were speedily subjected to prosecutions 
 and persecutions not unlike those which Marat had had 
 to endure from the Parisian police. Many were the 
 expedients adopted to evade the law. Large parcels of 
 waste paper labelled Poor Man's Guardian, were often 
 despatched from Hetherington's front door, and were 
 valiantly defended by the bearers against the police, 
 while the copies of the paper were being smuggled out 
 by a back door or over the roofs. Cleave adopted the 
 device of sham funerals from neighbours' houses, the 
 coffins being filled with his Police Gazettes. A "victim 
 fund" was started to pay the fines of printers or salesmen 
 who were convicted, and to lessen the hardships of the 
 five hundred or more persons who suffered imprisonment 
 for their devotion to the cause. Hetherington saw his 
 business melt away under the hostility of wealthier 
 neighbours, who probably were alarmed by the political 
 programme universal suffrage, vote by ballot, short 
 Parliaments, and no property qualification for mem- 
 bers which he unceasingly advocated. Filled with as 
 fanatical a zeal as the French revolutionists, whom he 
 ever held up to admiration, Hetherington extended his 
 operations into the provinces, his journal gaining a large 
 sale in Lancashire. Three terms of imprisonment failed 
 to shake the firmness of his purpose, or to injure the 
 sale of his paper. In fact, he started similar weekly 
 papers, the Republican and the Destructive, which were 
 still more revolutionary in their aims ; and when, owing 
 to various causes, the sale of his first paper declined, he 
 met the popular demand for more general news and less 
 diatribe by starting his Twopenny Despatch. Meanwhile 
 others had followed his example. John Cleave, a prin- 
 ter, who retained the bluff bearing and love of liberty of
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 73 
 
 his early seafaring- days, brought out his celebrated Police 
 Gazette, which soon attained an immense circulation, and 
 conducted its editor twice to prison. Carlisle's Gaunt- 
 let, another Radical and freethought journal, enjoyed a 
 weekly sale of 22,000 copies, or more than four times 
 that of Robert Owen's Crisis, which was losing ground. 
 Watson, the editor of The Working Man's Friend, and 
 Mr. William Carpenter, editor of The Political Magazine, 
 also felt the weight of the government's displeasure. 
 Besides these well-known weekly unstamped papers, a 
 swarm of disreputable prints some 150 in all, says 
 Francis Place bore witness to the depth of popular 
 ignorance and of hatred against the government. 
 
 But despite all the violence of the unstamped press, 
 public opinion set steadily in favour of the law-breakers, 
 even before the law was stultified by the declaration of 
 a jury that the Poor Man's Guardian was not an illegal 
 production. This verdict was largely due to the signal 
 ability with which Hetherington turned the tables on 
 his prosecutors, convicting them of gross injustice in 
 persecuting him while they allowed expensive journals 
 like the Lancet, Literary Gazette, Athenceum, and Legal 
 Observer to go scot-free. After the verdict of the jury on 
 June 17, 1834, the fourpenny stamp duty was doomed. 
 
 Eminent men like George Grote, the historian, and 
 even one of the Rothschilds, signed a requisition for a 
 public meeting, to be held at the Guildhall, advocating 
 the complete abolition of the taxes on knowledge; and 
 though The Times and The Morning Chronicle discoun- 
 tenanced the agitation, yet they were speedily silenced 
 by the establishment of an unstamped threepenny daily 
 paper, and secretly urged the Whig ministry to lower 
 the duty to one penny, a figure at which few editors 
 would be likely to brave the risks of prosecution. Un- 
 fortunately, their influence prevailed over the almost 
 unanimous voice of public opinion; and though the
 
 74 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 chancellor of the exchequer, Mr. Spring Rice, in 1835-36 
 had a surplus of a million sterling in the nation's budget, 
 yet he clung to the penny duty, claiming that as the 
 nation carried stamped newspapers free of postage, it 
 must make some equivalent charge, and that it would be 
 very hard on country readers to make them pay postage 
 on their papers! The grotesqueness of this excuse is 
 only equalled by its insincerity in days when government, 
 with unruffled equanimity, charged eightpence on a letter 
 from London to Brighton. It was in vain that deputa- 
 tions and petitions poured in to plead for a penny postage 
 for newspapers in place of the detested stamp duty ; and 
 there was a general outburst of indignation when it was 
 known that the reduction of the duty to one penny would 
 be accompanied by stringent regulations, aiming at the 
 complete extinction of the unstamped press and pam- 
 phlets. 
 
 At once the democrats were up in arms, the artisans 
 being especially inflamed against the proposals. For 
 some weeks past an American gentleman, Dr. Black, 
 had been organizing a class of London working-men for 
 correspondence respecting a free press, and now in the 
 midst of the agitation this class widened into the " Lon- 
 don Working Men's Association to procure a Cheap and 
 Honest Press". It was known and even admitted by the 
 government that a penny duty and the proposed regula- 
 tions would raise the price of a lawful journal to fourpence, 
 which was far beyond the means of working-men. Their 
 friends in the House of Commons, including Sir W. 
 Molesworth, and Messrs. Grote, Bulwer Lytton, Hume, 
 and others, made a spirited effort to gain its complete 
 abolition. It was in vain. Mr. Spring Rice, deeply 
 impressed by the fears of the propertied classes, and by 
 the interests of their journals, spent most of his ability 
 in proving the impossibility of carrying on the fourpenny 
 stamp duty, and in demonstrating the improvement
 
 The Fight for a Free Press. 75 
 
 effected in the morals of the unstamped papers as they 
 increased their circulation. The argument proved too 
 much and too little. It failed to calm the fears of the 
 Tories, or to win them from their adhesion to the rival 
 cause of cheap soap; and its timorous inconsequence 
 further widened the schism between Whigs and demo- 
 crats. 
 
 The same half-hearted policy was pursued with regard 
 to the paper-tax, which was reduced to three halfpence 
 per pound. Both changes chiefly benefited the publica- 
 tions read by the middle classes. The Times, Morning 
 Chronicle, Standard, &c., reduced their price tofivepence, 
 while the weekly Spectator came down to ninepence. The 
 small cheap newspapers were of course handicapped by 
 the new severe regulations, and by the new duty, which 
 pressed with far greater weight on a small print than on 
 the large and influential newspapers. 
 
 For various reasons the free press agitation declined 
 after 1836. Public attention was distracted by the ac- 
 cession of a young and beloved sovereign, by the general 
 enforcement of the new Poor-law, and by other stirring 
 events of the time. But, as will shortly appear, the free- 
 press movement, though making little headway until 
 after 1850, had an important effect on the first develop- 
 ment of Chartism. 
 
 The second agitation for the complete repeal of all 
 taxes on knowledge will be noticed more fully in the bio- 
 graphy of John Bright, which forms part of this series. 
 It may, however, be noted here that the essentially 
 working-man's movement of 183036 was in 1850-60 
 taken up by the middle -class leaders, Messrs. Bright, 
 Cobden, Villiers, Milner Gibson, and Baines. A Press 
 Association was also started, the proprietors and editors 
 of the more expensive journals having seen the folly of 
 their opposition to the abolition of the duty in 1836. The 
 contention for a complete repeal of the duties on news-
 
 76 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 papers, paper, and advertisements was, in fact, an ex- 
 tension of the free-trade policy commenced by Peel in 
 1842, which substituted a tax on property for the vexa- 
 tious imposts on raw materials and articles of common 
 use. 
 
 The repeal of the taxes on knowledge was a fore- 
 gone conclusion when the beneficial results of the re- 
 duction of the newspaper tax were seen in the doubling 
 of the circulation of newspapers within eight years. The 
 improvement in the tone of the press was equally marked, 
 affording gratifying proof of the advance in popular in- 
 telligence, which rejected the ribald and seditious trash 
 of the early unstamped prints. Those illegal journals 
 had, however, done a great work in compelling the Whig 
 ministry to advance with the times. Out of the lawless 
 prints there was gradually evolved that marvel of these 
 latter days, a cheap press, which may fitly be called the 
 fourth estate of the realm. If it be true, as surely it 
 is, that democracy can only be successfully worked by 
 well-informed citizens, then no steps can be regarded 
 with more satisfaction than those which have placed 
 the knowledge of public affairs within the reach of the 
 poorest. It was the boast of Pericles that in Athens 
 even the busy man took a lively interest in all the con- 
 cerns of the city. But the cheap newspaper now puts it 
 in the power of the artisan to follow the events of the 
 day, not only of his own town, but of his country, and 
 of the world at large. What a prospect of mental and 
 civic development is thus opened up, when once the 
 mind of the populace shall be raised above the level of 
 the sordid details which now too often hold it enthralled!
 
 Crown, Parliament, and People. 77 
 
 Chapter V. 
 Crown, Parliament, and People (1837). 
 
 The popular impression as to the Chartist movement 
 would seem to be that it was a sudden and almost 
 causeless outburst of Radical fanaticism; but a study 
 of those years reveals its intimate connection with the 
 movements championed by Major Cartwright, Cobbett, 
 Hunt, Lovett, and Hetherington, and also with the 
 popular indignation aroused by the harsh Whig Poor- 
 law of 1834 and the press regulations of 1836. The 
 concurrent effect of these various causes was to be fully 
 felt in the first years of the present reign, when the new 
 poor-law Bastilles were ready to receive their Oliver 
 Twists, and when even the industrious poor were often 
 forced into them by the dearth of corn and stagnation 
 of trade. Keen-sighted observers had foretold that the 
 new Poor-law would necessitate the repeal of the Corn- 
 laws, and many were the congratulations to the Whig 
 ministry on the bounteous harvests of 1834-1836, which 
 in those years assuaged the hardships consequent on the 
 withdrawal of the weekly dole in aid of wages. 
 
 But Fortune, after showering her favours on us, with- 
 drew them as suddenly in the first years of Queen 
 Victoria's reign, and thus revealed the close connection 
 then subsisting between a good harvest and the pros- 
 perity of all branches of our manufacturing industry. 
 When bread was dear, so large a share of the income 
 of artisan and shopkeeper went to the landlord, the 
 farmer, and the baker that other trades languished from 
 the decline in the purchasing power of the community. 
 Hence arose those complaints of over-production, which, 
 as Carlyle remarked in his Chartism, were inherently 
 absurd when myriad bare backs shivered for lack of
 
 78 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 sufficient clothing. Another serious symptom appeared 
 in our social life. At the time when Lancashire and 
 Yorkshire bemoaned the lack of purchasers for their 
 goods, the new facilities for migration offered by the 
 new Poor-law began to burden them with the surplus 
 pauper population, which, unable any longer to loaf out 
 its existence in the parishes of the southern and south- 
 midland counties, tramped towards the fabled wealth of 
 the factory towns. The result may readily be imagined. 
 Our manufacturing districts were crowded with miser- 
 able creatures, whose eagerness to take any work at any 
 pay depressed the condition of the regular operatives, 
 and foredoomed strikes to almost certain failure. The 
 position of the new-comers was miserable in the extreme. 
 An observer describes them as generally huddled to- 
 gether in filthy cellars, helpless to make a new start 
 in life, and as strange to the wealthy manufacturers as 
 were the aborigines of Australia. 1 Thus the coinci- 
 dence of a series of bad harvests with the completion of 
 the new harsh arrangements of the Poor-law gave the 
 last turn to the thumb-screw of misery, and brought 
 England to the verge of a social revolution. Lord 
 Bacon pithily remarks : "If poverty and broken estate 
 in the better sort be joined with want and necessity in 
 the mean people, the danger is imminent and great. 
 For the rebellions of the belly are the worst." That 
 was the state of Great Britain in the first five years of 
 the Victorian era. 
 
 And yet, even when beset by extraordinary difficulties 
 at home as well as in India and Canada, our beloved 
 land, so far from succumbing, was about to enter on the 
 most remarkable and glorious period of expansion and 
 growth which any European country has ever experi- 
 
 1 Dr. Cooke Taylor's Tour in Lancashire, which states that out of 17,000 
 destitute persons recently relieved at a refuge in Manchester, only 3500 
 were natives of the county.
 
 Crown, Parliament, and People. 79 
 
 enced. It may not, perhaps, be over-fanciful to trace 
 the action of a compensating- principle in our affairs, 
 securing 1 us from continental wars when our domestic 
 affairs threatened a crisis, and breathing- new life into 
 our institutions shortly before their subjection to an 
 unwonted strain. The life of Parliament had been reno- 
 vated by the enfranchisement of the middle classes, so 
 that the terrible social and industrial problems of the 
 new age were confronted, not by a close oligarchy, but 
 by a House of Commons representing the new energy 
 and wealth of the nation. Our old parliamentary system 
 had corrected many of its worst defects, thereby falsi- 
 fying the confident prophecies of democrats, that nothing 
 could be expected from a Parliament of borough-mongers. 
 Events, therefore, presaged evolution rather than a revo- 
 lution like that of France in the preceding century. In 
 that unhappy land, after the overthrow of the crumbling 
 walls of privilege, there was neither solidity in her insti- 
 tutions nor solidarity in her classes sufficient to stem the 
 inrushing tide of democratic innovation ; and power 
 speedily fell into the hands of enthusiasts, who involved 
 their country in wars that ultimately led her back to 
 despotism. 
 
 Ours was a happier lot. Peace, retrenchment, and 
 reform strengthened our institutions when threatened 
 by dangers as great as those of France in 1789; and 
 when industrial and social problems bulked threateningly 
 on the horizon, a new radiance was shed on the nation's 
 life by the accession of a young and beloved princess. 
 The happy results of the decease of George IV. have 
 already been noticed; and his brother, after outliving 
 his earlier popularity, now conferred a similar benefit 
 on mankind by an equally timely departure. The nation 
 hailed with joy the accession of the young Queen Vic- 
 toria, whose training at Kensington Palace by the 
 fondest and wisest of mothers had seemed to devote her
 
 8o The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 to a life healthier and purer than that of the court at 
 Windsor under her uncle's regime. The curious had 
 long remarked the simple natural life led by the young 
 princess, and opined that her reign might perhaps be 
 as prosperous and glorious as those of the last three 
 English queens who had reigned in their own right over 
 a loyal and devoted people. All the auguries seemed 
 favourable when the young queen "tears in her eyes, 
 but quite collected" hastily robed herself in the early 
 morning of June 20, 1837, to accept the allegiance of 
 the archbishop and the lord chancellor. Sentiment deep- 
 ened into admiration when, in her speech read at the 
 opening of the new Parliament, she declared that she 
 placed unreservedly at its disposal the moneys of the 
 Civil List a step which the late king had taken only 
 grudgingly and with reservations. Parliament ultimately 
 fixed the Civil List at ^385,000, withdrawing from 
 royal control some considerable items. 1 The new accord 
 between crown and Parliament was seen when the claim 
 of the trusty watch-dog Hume for a further reduction in 
 the Civil List was supported by only nineteen members. 
 Two years later, amidst the tumults of the autumn of 
 1839, a welcome proof of the people's loyalty was seen 
 in the universal acclaim which greeted the news of the 
 queen's approaching marriage with Prince Albert. 
 
 These details have a more than personal interest. 
 They distinguish the Radical and Chartist movement 
 from the republicanism which then characterized con- 
 tinental democracy. Frenchmen who strove for a pure 
 and economical administration regarded the sordid rule 
 of Louis Philippe with increasing aversion; every en- 
 lightened Prussian chafed under the patriarchal sway 
 of Frederick William IV.; and few Italians who longed 
 
 1 The assumption by Parliament of larger controlling powers over the 
 crown estates, and the fixing of the Civil List, have resulted in a considerable 
 gain to the nation's finance.
 
 Crown, Parliament, and People. 81 
 
 for the liberty of their peninsula could regard the Pope 
 or the Bourbons of Naples with the feelings cherished 
 by Englishmen towards Queen Victoria. Radicals might 
 complain of the etiquette which prevented them peti- 
 tioning the queen, unless they presented themselves in 
 all the glory of court dress at her majesty's levde; but, 
 though indulging in the Englishman's cherished privi- 
 lege, a far-resounding grumble, they knew full well that 
 the queen's heart beat in sympathy with the people's 
 cares and aspirations. Every cottager admired the 
 womanly fondness which refused to part with the ladies 
 of the bed-chamber in obedience to the dictates of a sup- 
 posed parliamentary tradition; and the marriage of the 
 queen in Feb., 1840, entwined still closer those bonds 
 of affection between crown and people which had been 
 all but ruptured in the reign of George IV. The fierce 
 republicanism of that generation gradually faded away 
 before the simpler, nobler, and more sympathetic influ- 
 ences which shone from her of whom Tennyson has 
 sung 
 
 " A thousand claims to reverence closed 
 In her as mother, wife, and queen ". 
 
 But while the crown was regaining its hold on the 
 people's affections, the Whig ministry was feeling the 
 brunt of the unpopularity which is the guerdon of power 
 in times of distress. The general election of August, 
 1837, left the Whigs with a slender majority over their 
 newly-styled Conservative opponents, ably led by Sir 
 Robert Peel. The leader of the Whig ministry, Lord 
 Melbourne, was not a tower of strength to his anxious 
 following. Indeed, apart from his chivalrous interest 
 in the political training of the young queen, he seemed 
 to find political life a sheer weariness. In receiving 
 a deputation, his chief desire appeared to be to pose 
 gracefully as a modern Gallic, heedless of the important 
 
 (M416) V
 
 8a The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 issues brought before him ; and his colleagues failed to 
 remove the impression that the ministry either would 
 not, or could not, assuage the deepening distress of the 
 country. Lord Glenelg's conduct towards the Canadian 
 malcontents inspired no confidence on either side of the 
 Atlantic; Mr Spring Rice failed for five years to present 
 a clean balance-sheet, and the fate of the ministry de- 
 pended on the energy of one sprightly personality, Lord 
 John Russell. "If (wrote Sydney Smith) the amiable 
 Lord Glenelg were to leave us, we should feel secure in 
 our colonial possessions ; if Mr. Spring Rice were to go 
 into holy orders, great would be the joy of the three per 
 cents. A decent, good-looking head of the government 
 might easily be found in lieu of Viscount Melbourne. 
 But in five minutes after the departure of Lord John 
 Russell, the whole Whig government would be dissolved 
 into sparks of Liberality and splinters of Reform." And 
 yet the one clever man of the ministry never enjoyed any 
 general popularity. The scion of the ducal house of 
 Bedford seemed to hold aloof from the rank and file of 
 his followers, either from aristocratic reserve, or from a 
 certain "lofty shyness" of character to use a phrase 
 felicitously applied by Lord Rosebery to the younger 
 Pitt. Both Pitt and Russell, on throwing off the cares 
 of office, became the most charming of talkers when 
 amidst congenial society. But their frigid demeanour in 
 the House often cooled their friends and heated their 
 opponents, giving to their refusals, their rebukes, or 
 their sarcasms an asperity which probably was never 
 intended. Lord John Russell's facility in giving offence 
 is thus happily hit off by Lord Lytton : 
 
 " Next, cool, and all unconscious of reproach, 
 Comes the calm 'Johnny, who upset the coach'. 
 How formed to lead, if not too proud to please 
 His fame would fire you, but his manners freeze.
 
 Crown, Parliament, and People. 83 
 
 Like or dislike, he does not care a jot, 
 
 He wants your votes, but your affections not." 1 
 
 This lack of paying parliamentary manners undoubtedly 
 increased the annoyance felt by Radicals at an important 
 declaration of policy by the Whig leader in the House of 
 Commons. It was called forth by amendments being 
 proposed to the first queen's speech (Nov., 1837), de- 
 manding an extension of the franchise. To this Lord John 
 offered an uncompromising opposition, urging that the 
 reform of 1832 had been made as extensive as possible 
 in the hope that it might be final ; that the reopening of 
 the question of the franchise would destroy the stability 
 of our institutions; and that he personally could not 
 assent to the amendments without being guilty of a 
 "breach of faith and honour". This declaration, so 
 creditable to Lord John Russell as a man, excited the 
 liveliest discontent among advanced reformers, who 
 thenceforth dubbed him "Finality Jack". But Radicals 
 proved that they could do more than invent nicknames. 
 With remorseless logic they proved to the Whigs that 
 the measure of 1832 could not be final. There were 
 two principles upon which the people's representatives 
 could be elected : they could represent either the landed 
 wealth of the country, or the people of the United King- 
 dom. If the former were taken as the basis of repre- 
 sentation, then the apportionment of two members to 
 Old Sarum was at any rate intelligible, perhaps even 
 defensible. But the Reform Bill of 1832 had decided in 
 favour of Manchester and against Old Sarum. On what 
 principle but that of population could this have been 
 adopted? It was not the wealth of Manchester which 
 was thenceforth to be represented in Parliament, but the 
 opinion of the people of that town ; and if so, why not 
 that of all the men who could think for themselves? 
 
 1 Spencer Walpole's Life of Lord J. Russell, vol. i. chap. 12.
 
 84 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 The argument was irresistible; and whatever "Finality 
 Jack" might say, the operatives of England regarded the 
 Act of 1832 as a mere half-way house toward household 
 suffrage. 
 
 The breach between Whigs and Radicals now rapidly 
 widened, with the result that many of the powerful 
 political associations started duringthe long and desperate 
 struggle for reform were now turned against the party 
 which they had, five years previously, helped to power. 
 Such, then, was the political position in 1837: our 
 artisans permeated by levelling ideas concerning pro- 
 perty; the newly-enfranchised middle class pot-bound 
 by narrow and sordid interests; the aristocracy mainly 
 occupied in "preserving their game"; Parliament imbued 
 with the smug complacency and brusque self-assertion 
 of the Plugsons and modern Taillefers ; the crown alone 
 resplendent with a renewed lustre. The outlook was 
 ominous. Indeed, few years of peace have been more 
 critical than the first five of the Victorian era. But for 
 the succession of a popular sovereign, and the hope, 
 ever-cherished though often deferred, of influencing the 
 House of Commons by peaceful agitation, our institu- 
 tions could scarcely have survived the strain. 
 
 Chapter VI. 
 The Rise of Chartism (1838-1839). 
 
 The foregoing description will have shown how 
 favourable were the conditions in our national life for 
 the rise of a formidable democratic agitation. A bad 
 harvest, and a serious commercial crisis in 1837, com- 
 pleted the difficulties of the queen's ministers. Their 
 acts and their words were scanned with jealous scrutiny
 
 The Rise of Chartism. 85 
 
 by Tories in the House and by democrats in the country. 
 To the parliamentary annalist the Tory gains seemed of 
 chief importance. We can now see that the future of 
 English institutions was being decided, not so much at 
 Westminster, as in the workmen's clubs of our land. 
 
 Great commotion had been caused there by recent 
 ministerial utterances. Lord John Russell's command 
 to the billows of democracy " Hitherto shalt thou 
 come, but no further" had only served to recall the 
 historic defiance of Mrs. Partington to the ocean. The 
 tide was beginning to turn in against the bulwarks 
 reared in 1832. The London Working-men's Associa- 
 tion, irritated by the retention of a penny duty on each 
 newspaper, and by regulations which portended ruin to 
 the cheapest journals, was demanding a drastic reform 
 of Parliament. In a carefully-written pamphlet, The 
 Rotten House of Commons (Dec., 1836), the secretary, 
 Lovett, had proved from official returns that, out of the 
 total number of 6,023,752 adult males in the United 
 Kingdom, only 839,519 had votes -, while such were the 
 inequalities in the size of the constituencies that 20 
 members were returned by 2411 voters, while 20 more 
 represented as many as 86,072 electors. Fortified by 
 these facts, the members of the association convened a 
 public meeting at the Crown and Anchor in the Strand 
 for giving cohesion to the demands which now were 
 urged in various quarters; and some 3000 persons 
 adopted and petitioned for what were soon to be called 
 the "six points" of the People's Charter viz., universal 
 suffrage, abolition of property qualification for members 
 of Parliament, annual Parliaments, equal representation, 
 payment of members of Parliament, and vote by ballot 
 at elections. 
 
 The derivation of this new Radical programme from 
 that which was put forward in 1780 has already been 
 explained. It illustrates that continuity of life, that
 
 86 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 tenacious clinging to old rights which have been our best 
 safeguard against both despotism and revolution. The 
 similarity of the programmes of 1780 and 1838 extends 
 even to details, the clauses as to registration of voters, 
 and the division of counties into equal electoral districts 
 each returning one member, being almost identical. 
 The thoroughly English custom of appealing to prece- 
 dent is also observable in both documents, Lovett's 
 introduction to the Charter referring to its identity with 
 the proposals of 1780, while the earlier programme care- 
 fully based its claim for household suffrage on the old 
 principle of "no representation no taxation", and that 
 for payment of representatives on " the wholesome 
 practice of ancient times". 
 
 The "six points" were formulated by the London 
 Working-men's Association in the last days of William 
 IV.'s reign; and a committee of six of their members 
 was appointed to confer with six Radical members of 
 Parliament for the drafting of a bill which should give 
 legal expression to these demands. It is clear from the 
 details given by Lovett in his Autobiography that the 
 chief impulse did not come from the parliamentary repre- 
 sentatives, but from the working-men. Mr. Roebuck, 
 M.P., well known by his sobriquet Tear 'em, and 
 Lovett were, after some delay, deputed to draft the bill; 
 but owing to Roebuck's championship of the cause of 
 the Canadian insurgents, the work was performed almost 
 entirely by Lovett. At last, on May 8, 1838, the docu- 
 ment was published. In an able introduction Lovett 
 referred to the new democratic measure "as a Charter 
 they were determined to obtain ". In this phrase, and 
 in a subsequent remark by O'Connell "There, Lovett, 
 is your Charter : agitate for it, and never be content with 
 anything less" may be found the origin of the term 
 applied not only to the proposed People's Bill, but to the 
 party and the movement. At the outset, the agitation
 
 The Rise of Chartism. 87 
 
 was thoroughly constitutional. Lovett called the atten- 
 tion of all the working-men's associations to the Whig- 
 origin of the programme, and contrasted the apathy of 
 that party, when installed in power, with their earlier 
 professions, using this as an argument for rendering all 
 parties alike responsible to the people. 
 
 The new movement, however, claims our attention, 
 not only from its immense influence on our political life, 
 but also owing to the moral fervour actuating its votaries. 
 In common with Hetherington, Vincent, Place, and 
 others, who struggled for the mental and moral im- 
 provement of artisans, Lovett had insisted on the need 
 of a higher ideal of life, if they were wisely to discharge 
 the political rights for which they were struggling. The 
 aims of the London Association, formed in 1836, had 
 been primarily "to create a moral, reflecting, energetic 
 public opinion, so as eventually to lead to a gradual im- 
 provement in the condition of the working-classes, with- 
 out violence or commotion " ; to unite the honest, sober, 
 moral, and thinking portion of their brethren; to form 
 libraries and debating societies; to gain a cheap and 
 honest press; to avoid meeting at public-houses; to 
 instruct women and children with a view to domestic 
 happiness; "for, be assured, the good that is to be 
 must be begun by ourselves ". 
 
 It would be interesting, did space permit, fully to 
 compare these enlightened aims with the views set forth 
 by Carlyle, Owen, and Mazzini. Seven years had elapsed 
 since the gifted Scotsman had published, in his essay 
 Signs of the Times, his first indictment against the age, 
 that men were struggling not for internal perfection but 
 for external combinations, for institutions and constitu- 
 tions. As a criticism of the later phases of Chartism, 
 and, indeed, of latter-day democracy both in England 
 and on the Continent, this assertion would have been 
 perfectly justified; but the extracts above cited prove
 
 88 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 conclusively that the founders of Chartism were fully 
 convinced of the futility of mere external reforms for 
 which there had been no preparation in the life of the 
 people. All intelligent democrats Schiller in Germany, 
 Pestalozzi in Switzerland, and Robert Owen, the " wilful 
 Welshman " had realized that the failure of democracy 
 in France was due to the lack of that power of self- 
 restraint, of that sense of duty to one's fellows, which 
 forms the moral cement of society. Indeed, this con- 
 viction may be regarded as one of the most vitalizing 
 truths of the early part of this century, inspiring many 
 of the educational, philanthropic, and political efforts 
 which sought to alleviate the ever-increasing mass of 
 misery. 
 
 " Ah ! your Fouriers failed 
 Because not poets enough to understand 
 That life develops from within." 
 
 This truth, uttered by our most gifted poetess, was being 
 seen by all who had either the eye to gaze beneath the 
 surface, or the sense to bring their schemes to the test 
 of experience. Even Owen's experiments in education 
 and co-operation were to have fruitful results, so far as 
 they helped to mould character and awaken to new in- 
 quiry. His educational aim, far in advance of his age, 
 was to fashion fully formed men and women who would 
 always act in a rational manner, and respond, not to 
 force, but to reason. The origin of moral-force Chartism 
 is clearly traceable to the conviction which the compilers 
 of the Charter had imbibed from Robert Owen as to the 
 innate reasonableness of well-educated persons, and the 
 social felicity attainable under conditions which gave 
 equal opportunity to all. 
 
 But the highest note sounded by the early Chartist 
 leaders also rings responsive to Mazzini's clarion call of 
 duty. Facts forbid the assumption, otherwise so attrac-
 
 The Rise of Chartism. 89 
 
 tive, that the leading artisans of London could have had 
 any direct contact with the great Italian thinker before 
 the early part of 1837, when he came as an exile to our 
 metropolis. True, he had, two years earlier, given to 
 the world his prophetic work, Faith and the Future; but its 
 circulation appears to have been then limited to Switzer- 
 land. A remarkable though unconscious parallelism, 
 however, exists between the views of the early Chartists 
 and those of the Italian democrat who claimed that the 
 struggle for individual rights could but end in anarchy; 
 while a sense of social duty alone could build up a peace- 
 ful and noble commonwealth. The struggle for rights, 
 Mazzini asserted, could only destroy, not found ; whereas 
 duty associated and constructed. The former killed 
 self-sacrifice and banished martyrdom from the world; 
 whereas duty nerved men to lifelong and disinterested 
 endeavour. The life of Mazzini and the history of latter- 
 day democracy form an instructive commentary on these 
 opposing aims and principles. 
 
 The falling away of Chartism from its first ideals 
 cannot be ascribed to the men who struggled equally 
 for the moral improvement and the political enfranchise- 
 ment of the masses. At first their belief in the power 
 of reason and persuasion seemed fully justified. Their 
 movement began to forge ahead steadily and peacefully 
 in the teeth of many adverse circumstances. Nothing 
 is so dangerous as aimless and hopeless misery. The 
 critical stage of a movement is really well-nigh passed 
 when turbulent and truculent harangues give way to a 
 settled conviction that a remedy is attainable. It was 
 now the aim of the chief Chartist speakers, among whom 
 Vincent and Hetherington were prominent, to prove that 
 they could and would gain from Parliament the political 
 power achieved by the "shopocracy" in 1832. Vincent's 
 glowing and impassioned oratory, and the more logical 
 and closely reasoned speeches of Hetherington, told with
 
 90 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 great effect on different types of mind, the former speaker 
 arousing immense interest, which the latter clinched with 
 the grip of conviction. Political clubs were started in 
 several towns, and from feeble beginnings soon grew 
 into formidable bodies. The People's Charter was en- 
 thusiastically accepted by immense meetings at Glasgow 
 and Birmingham, in May and August of 1838, and the 
 new agitation received the support of very many of the 
 middle classes, and of their journals. At the former of 
 these meetings Dr. Wade, the well-known writer on 
 industrial and social questions, significantly stated that 
 they had enough physical force behind them, but that 
 they would rely solely on moral force to gain their per- 
 fectly legitimate aims. 
 
 Such is, in brief outline, a sketch of the chief moral- 
 force Chartists and of their aims. With some of these 
 it is impossible not to feel sympathy. Had all the cir- 
 cumstances of the time been favourable to steady and 
 rapid social advancement of the proletariate, it seems 
 probable that these men might have speedily succeeded 
 in raising the working-men of England to a higher plane 
 of thought and action. It is even possible that they 
 might have peacefully gained for their fellows a great 
 extension of political rights and duties, such as has been 
 ultimately secured through the working of our party 
 system. 
 
 It was not to be. The prospects of the movement 
 were soon to be overclouded by the admixture of ' ' physi- 
 cal-force" elements, which represented the cruder and 
 fiercer forces at work in our social life. But, before we 
 notice the warping influence exerted by those who more 
 or less openly advocated recourse to violence, we must 
 glance at the events transpiring at Birmingham, where 
 the second mass meeting of the Chartists was held. 
 Public affairs there were largely under the control of the 
 Birmingham Political Union, an important association
 
 The Rise of Chartism. gr 
 
 founded mainly for aiding- the reformers in 1830-1832. 
 It had recently been revived by its founder, Thomas 
 Attwood, who at that time wielded considerable influence 
 in the Midlands. Yet it is difficult to believe that the 
 men of Birmingham ever took him altogether seriously. 
 A fellow-townsman, Mr. G. J. Holyoake, describes him 
 as a Royalist and Radical, not remarkable for intellectual 
 strength, but endowed with a dignified presence and the 
 faculty of persuasive speech. These qualities, and his 
 control of the local newspaper, partly account for his 
 being returned as one of the two members which Bir- 
 mingham first sent to Westminster. That town must 
 either have been deeply imbued with the provincialism 
 which Mr. Holyoake notes as a feature of the Midland 
 mind; or possibly his election may be ascribed to a 
 vigorous canvass, in which he is said to have kissed 
 8000 mothers and their offspring. At any rate, by what- 
 ever means acquired, Attwood enjoyed immense popu- 
 larity in Birmingham, though his reforming zeal seems 
 to have been little more than skin-deep. Resting in 
 complacent contentment with the 10 franchise of 1832, 
 Attwood allowed the Birmingham Political Union to 
 lapse, in 1834, until his failure to convince Parliament 
 of the supreme importance of his own currency fads led 
 him again to dally with democracy. The adoption by 
 Parliament of stringent currency measures, in the autumn 
 of 1836, certainly tended to stimulate an impending indus- 
 trial crisis, and gave Attwood the opportunity of reviving 
 his Union (December, 1836), and of airing his own cur- 
 rency scheme. His popular manners, his suave speech 
 resplendent with golden vistas of prosperity, and, above 
 all, his proprietary rights in the Union, and in the 
 only newspaper which the Midland capital then boasted, 
 carried the day there for paper currency and the Charter. 
 The latter, in Attwood's eyes, was to be as subservient 
 to the former as the artisans to their middle-class leaders.
 
 92 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Now, it would have needed immense persuasive powers 
 to have reconciled artisans who hankered after a division 
 of property, to the lead of so typical a bourgeois as Att- 
 wood ; and he possessed few of the needed qualifications, 
 except fluency. Even his orations, though popular at 
 the time, aroused suspicions as to the real extent of his 
 mental powers. He rarely concluded a lengthy harangue 
 without contradicting the commencement. At the famous 
 Chartist meeting at Holloway Head, Birmingham, in 
 August, 1838, the enormous length of the procession, 
 the blare of bands and waving of banners, seem to have 
 confused his notions of moral force and physical force ; 
 for after stating at the outset that he would never sanction 
 the commission of violence, he exclaimed in his peroration 
 that if the government dared to arrest him, 100,000 men 
 should march to demand his release. Not only his ora- 
 tions but his political schemes seemed to be permeated 
 with hysteria. Emotional indeed must have been the 
 mind which could recommend the working-classes to 
 rest from their toil a whole week a "sacred week" 
 devoted to peaceful agitation! Yet to the end of his 
 career he persisted in justifying this by the legendary 
 incident of the secession of the Roman plebs to the 
 Aventine. A flood of light is thrown upon his character 
 by his sketch, written two years later, of the idyllic pro- 
 ceedings which were to grace the sacred week. " On 
 the first day we will offer up on our bended knee a 
 solemn prayer to God for his blessing on our righteous 
 cause. On the second we will enter into a solemn league 
 and covenant with each other, swearing that we will 
 never cease from legal exertions until the National Peti- 
 tion shall have been carried into a law. The third day 
 of the week we will devote to a general canvass of 
 all the electors of the House of Commons: and so we 
 will go on to the end of the week, which will be the most 
 memorable in the history of the world. I may perish:
 
 The Rise of Chartism. 93 
 
 but if I live to conduct this great operation, and the 
 people support me, I promise you that our country shall 
 exhibit such a sublime spectacle as the wide earth and 
 the wide range of history never before exhibited." 1 Such 
 was the man whose eccentric nature was to exercise a 
 comet-like influence on the nebulous life of newly en- 
 franchised Birmingham. 
 
 In clearness of view and strength of character Attwood 
 yielded the palm to a working-man named John Collins, 
 who soon acquired a reputation for straightforwardness 
 and for the courage with which he, along with Lovett, 
 dared the penalties of the law. His influence was to 
 outlast that of Attwood, as the flight of a bird outstrips 
 that of a butterfly ; and ultimately he did much to enroll 
 Birmingham Radicals in the Chartist ranks. 
 
 As regards details, we may note that the Birmingham 
 Political Union at first advocated merely household 
 suffrage (as against the universal suffrage of the Char- 
 ter) and triennial Parliaments, while it omitted equal 
 electoral districts. On the other hand, it laid stress on 
 payment of members of Parliament, and on the need of 
 a heavy property tax which should supersede all other 
 imposts. The indirect influence of these demands was 
 to be considerable. Artisans and no small part of the 
 shopkeepers of the Midlands, after going so far, were 
 soon led to adopt the complete Chartist programme; 
 and the tone of the Birmingham Journal became for a 
 time ultra-Radical if not distinctly Chartist. 
 
 In fact, the whole trend of events was favouring the 
 advanced wing of the party. If the moral-force men 
 derived their convictions from the teaching of Owen as 
 to the reasonableness of well-informed persons, the men 
 of force could with equal justice point to the hopeless- 
 ness of expecting constitutional action from the un- 
 taught, underfed masses. When oppressed by Corn- 
 
 1 See the Birming ham Journal of June 19, 1841.
 
 94 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 law and Poor-law alike, could these be expected to 
 keep the peace towards a government which, they 
 asserted, had tricked them in and after 1832, and was 
 using force to crush the justifiable discontent of the 
 Canadians? As has been already noted, the publication 
 of the Charter coincided with a time of intense distress 
 at home. The new Poor-law was being generally 
 enforced when corn was rising to an average of more 
 than sixty shillings per quarter; so that the cruel alter- 
 native of liberty with starvation or of state relief in 
 the workhouse confronted increasing numbers of the 
 respectable poor. The close of the year 1837 had 
 witnessed an outbreak in a Leicestershire workhouse 
 which was quelled only by military force. In Kent the 
 popular ignorance, credulity, and hatred of the new 
 law was seen in a riotous concourse of peasants which 
 gathered around a lunatic named Thorn, who proclaimed 
 himself the Saviour of the world, especially from the 
 injustice of the new Poor-law. On a body of troops 
 being sent against him from Canterbury, he shot their 
 commander dead. A volley from the soldiers ended his 
 life and scattered his dupes ; but they long afterwards 
 cherished the belief that their leader would reappear to 
 rid them of the new tyranny. 
 
 Far more serious was the discontent in the north of 
 England, where the old system of poor-relief had been 
 less abused than was the case in the southern and south- 
 midland counties, which the new Act of 1834 saved from 
 impending ruin. The "salutary harshness" to use 
 Carlyle's phrase of the new measure accordingly 
 aroused in the north a deep and passionate resentment, 
 which was to be the chief feeder of physical-force 
 Chartism. These feelings were most prominently ex- 
 pressed by two men, Stephens and Oastler, who always 
 called themselves Tories, but whose words and acts 
 fanned the embers of Radicalism well-nigh to a blaze.
 
 The Rise of Chartism. 95 
 
 Joseph Rayner Stephens was, or rather had been, 
 a Wesleyan minister at Ashton- under -Lyne; but his 
 championship of disestablishment had in 1834 caused 
 his removal from his pastoral charge for having "fla- 
 grantly violated the peaceable and antisectarian spirit of 
 Wesleyan Methodism". He thereupon flung himself 
 into the cause of factory reform, then being pressed on 
 by Oastler, Fielden, Sadler, and others; but his powers 
 of inflammatory speech were chiefly directed against 
 the poor-law commissioners and their work. Thus, at 
 Newcastle on January i, 1838, he threatened that if 
 their enactments were put in force, "Newcastle ought 
 to be, and should be, one blaze of fire, with only one 
 way to put it out, and that with the blood of all those 
 who supported this abominable law ". Later on, when 
 speaking at a banquet given to Mr. Fielden, M.P., for 
 his opposition to the law in Parliament, Stephens urged 
 the people to shed their blood rather than submit to 
 that law of devils, which evidently aimed at making 
 the new poor-law Bastilles a chain of barracks for the 
 " Russellite rural police", and for the subjection of a 
 free people. Words like these became highly dangerous 
 when uttered to large torch-light gatherings held around 
 many northern towns in the autumn of 1838, especially 
 when the emotional orator urged the need of muskets. 
 At last, at a vast meeting held at Hyde in Cheshire, 
 the orator, fired by the sight of faces lurid with hunger 
 and hatred, exclaimed that the time for action had come, 
 as the soldiers had been won over to the people's side; 
 and a challenge "Are you ready?" was answered by a 
 discharge of firearms. The authorities were now aroused 
 from their half-contemptuous toleration. Stephens was 
 arrested, and was condemned to eighteen months' im- 
 prisonment. Never had Lancashire and Cheshire been 
 nearer to open insurrection than on the receipt of this 
 news. Needy operatives showed their regard for the
 
 96 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 people's champion by subscribing nearly ^2000 for the 
 relief of his wife and family; and the man who was 
 already beginning to utilize this indignation for the 
 physical-force Chartists, won golden opinions by declar- 
 ing that, should the tyrannical government decide to 
 transport the people's champion, his manacled limbs 
 should pass to the convict ship only over the lifeless 
 body of Feargus O'Connor. 
 
 Much as we may sympathize with the characters and 
 even with many of the aims of the moral-force Chartists, 
 these men seem open to the charge of folly in expecting 
 that sweeping changes could be peaceably effected in our 
 constitution, when the masses of the people were so 
 ignorant and excitable as the foregoing recital proves 
 them to have been. The miserable conditions of life in 
 the factory townships had wrought a sinister change not 
 only in the well-being, but in the moral character of the 
 population; and much remedial work was to be done, 
 much legislation to be enacted, before so enlightened a 
 democrat as John Stuart Mill could give his vote for 
 the enfranchisement of all householders. Besides, the 
 Chartist programme itself was open to grave suspicions 
 of serving merely as a prelude to a forcible redistribution 
 of property; and there are grounds for believing that 
 the "six points" by themselves would not at that time 
 have aroused any wide-spread enthusiasm, had they not 
 been irradiated by the golden gleams of Owenism. 
 Neither expectant artisans nor timid bourgeois ever for- 
 got that Lovett, Hetherington, and other prominent 
 moral -force men were followers of the seer of New 
 Lanark, who promised that his system must peaceably 
 lead to equalization of fortune. It is true that many 
 of his followers, especially Lovett, had forsaken the 
 hazy fanaticism of Owen in favour of modern co-opera- 
 tive methods. Yet the Owenite taint clung about moral- 
 force Chartism even when it promised the inevitable
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 97 
 
 triumph of reason and the discomfiture of brute force. 
 All who knew what were the ulterior aims of Robert 
 Owen, and how wide was the popularity of Hodgkin's 
 levelling- dogmas, saw the futility of carrying out by 
 peaceful methods aims which at that time would have 
 produced revolutionary results. The discouragement 
 which overtook Lovett, Vincent, and others in the midst 
 of their political career may safely be attributed to more 
 than mere disgust at the vagaries of O'Connor. They 
 must have seen that they were in a false position, 
 ostensibly leading a movement that was propelled by 
 unscrupulous men who more correctly interpreted the 
 passions of the crowd. They were the Girondists of 
 English democracy, doomed to personal failure, though 
 some of their ideals were finally to be realized. For the 
 present, they saw popularity slip from their grasp into 
 that of Feargus O'Connor. 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 
 
 Rarely has any man leapt to popularity so deftly and 
 rapidly as the gifted Irishman, who was destined for 
 ten years to be the foremost of democratic leaders and 
 to take the place of O'Connell as the prince of mob 
 orators. Feargus O'Connor, who claimed descent from 
 a line of old Irish kings, first gained a reputation at the 
 Irish bar by his imposing presence, powerful voice, 
 rollicking wit, and consummate assurance. 
 
 His forensic successes were, however, only a prelude 
 to a wider popularity. It was in O'Connell's train, or 
 "tail" as irreverent Saxons termed it, that O'Connor 
 first displayed that power over a crowd which a robust 
 
 (M 416 ) G
 
 98 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 frame, stentorian tones, and fluent oratory generally 
 ensure. When elected member for Cork in 1833, he 
 soon came into collision with his equally masterful 
 leader, whose fitful acts of complaisance to the Whigs 
 were resented by his more Radical subaltern. As neither 
 could brook opposition, O'Connell was left in undisputed 
 sway in Ireland, while his ambitious compatriot sought 
 a new sphere of conquest in the discontented proletariate 
 of England. O'Connor's success in England was start- 
 Kng and complete. Continental writers who sneer at 
 John Bull's insularity are ignorant of the real catholicity 
 of taste which that much-maligned personage evinces in 
 the presence of genuine merit. The Athens of Pericles 
 was not more appreciative of sterling excellence in men 
 of another race, than were the English working-men on 
 whose feelings Feargus O'Connor played at will, who 
 in more recent times have hung in rapt attention on the 
 stately periods of the great Hungarian patriot Kossuth, 
 and have thronged to shake hands with Garibaldi. The 
 causes of O'Connor's success with the men of the Mid- 
 lands and North are not far to seek. His brawny frame, 
 thick neck, and distinguished air, appealed at once to 
 an athletic people ; and their hearts were won when the 
 descendant of a long line of kings roared forth his 
 denunciations of the Whig tyrants, or, darting from 
 grave to gay, described the treatment which he would 
 accord to "Harry Brougham and his wife" when their 
 power was overthrown and they came to the poorhouse 
 "Softly, my lady, you go not in with your spouse: 
 turn here, if you please, to the female ward". But popular 
 favour reached its climax when, as happened at New- 
 castle, O'Connor turned from the facetious topic of 
 workhouse discipline, and the restriction of pauper 
 population, to hurl defiance at the troops who were 
 marching up to the outskirts of the vast throng on the 
 Town Moor. A man whose presence was so command-
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 99 
 
 ing-, whose voice seemed to rend the welkin, whose 
 gibes called forth shouts of laughter, whose indignation 
 could excite a vast crowd to cries of defiance or ven- 
 geance, evidently possessed all the superficial charac- 
 teristics of a Danton. But fortunately for England and 
 for Chartism, O'Connor had neither the statesmanlike 
 width of view nor the persistent audacity which made 
 the leader of the French sans-culottes so potent a force 
 in 1792. It is true, the circumstances of 1792 and 1839 
 were widely different. Probably the heroes of sans-culot- 
 tism might have cut very sorry figures had they been 
 confronted by forces of law and order so commanding 
 as those of Queen Victoria's government; and possibly 
 Carlyle's verdict as to the Titanesque grandeur of Dan- 
 ton might have been modified, had his hero ever come 
 face to face with a greatly superior force of Parisian 
 special constables. Some allowance must be made for 
 the altered circumstances of the case. Feargus O'Con- 
 nor, indeed, took care to make every such allowance; 
 for in most of his physical-force outbursts he took refuge 
 in the immunity which attaches to poetical rhapsodies 
 such as 
 
 " Then onward, your green standards waving, 
 Go flesh every sword to the hilt !" 
 
 On other occasions he balanced his most inflammatory 
 appeals with a prudent superfluity of conditional clauses. 
 Of this latter device his speech in the Palace Yard, 
 Westminster (Sept. 17, 1838), offers a good example. 
 After cautioning the people against rioting and civil war 
 he continued "But still, in the hearing of the House 
 of Commons, I will say that rather than see the people 
 oppressed, rather than see the constitution violated 
 while the people are in daily want, why then, if no 
 other man will do so, I myself will lead them to death 
 or glory ".
 
 ioo The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 But Feargus O'Connor was to win glory, not only as 
 a highly entertaining orator, but as a most effective 
 journalist. He had already succeeded in the somewhat 
 hazardous enterprise of braving the newspaper regula- 
 tions enacted in 1836. In the course of his political 
 campaign of 1837, he accordingly appealed to some sub- 
 stantial men for help in the establishment of a Radical 
 weekly journal. Several of them clubbed together to 
 subscribe 800 for his venture the Northern Star and 
 Leeds Advertiser, the first number of which appeared 
 on Nov. 1 8, 1837. It was a large-sized paper of eight 
 pages, and was sold for fourpence halfpenny, the editor 
 being a Mr. Hill, and, later, the well-known physical- 
 force Chartist, George Julian Harney. At the outset, 
 however, it aimed at securing merely universal suffrage, 
 the immediate abolition of the Poor-law of 1834, "and 
 the establishment of a respectable provision, unattended 
 with degradation, for every unwilling idler in the state. 
 . . . We must endeavour to raise working men to a 
 state of perfect equality with their richer neighbours." 
 This pronouncement was evidently intended to attract 
 not only the political Radicals, but also Tory democrats 
 like Oastler and Stephens, and levellers imbued with the 
 theories of Spence and Hodgkin ; and even for some time 
 after the publication of the Charter, O'Connor continued 
 to deal in vague tirades and alluring promises. But, 
 skilfully trimming his sails to every shift of the popularis 
 aura, O'Connor took up the Chartist programme when 
 its popularity was assured by the great meeting at 
 Birmingham; and what he lacked in originating power 
 was more than atoned for by the increasing vehemence 
 of his advocacy. The defects of his speeches, their 
 tinsel rhetoric, shambling arguments, and random con- 
 clusions, were forgotten amidst the impression created 
 by his Celtic complaisance of manner and the rever- 
 berations of his stentorian voice, so that his dexterous
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 101 
 
 championship of physical force began to turn the scale 
 against the more prudent counsels of the best artisans 
 of London, Birmingham, and Edinburgh. 
 
 The great popularity of his paper, some 60,000 copies 
 of which were sold every week, not only increased his 
 influence, but depressed that of rivals. For a time he 
 had, as regular contributor, Bronterre O'Brien, a man of 
 great energy and ability, devoted to the levelling theories 
 of the day ; but before long ambition and love of power 
 led to their separation, amidst mutual exasperation. 
 Bronterre O'Brien was perhaps superior in mental train- 
 ing and attainments to all the Chartist leaders. He had 
 shown his journalistic powers in numerous articles written 
 for Hetherington's unstamped paper, and his literary skill 
 in a forcible defence of Robespierre. As an orator he 
 excelled equally in argument, satire, or passionate in- 
 vective ; while his grip on practical life was to be shown 
 by his merciless exposure of the silly scheme of a sacred 
 month. The antipathy existing between him and O'Con- 
 nor finally became an open feud, which seriously damaged 
 the Chartist cause. After leaving the Northern Star, 
 O'Brien started a paper called the Operative] but neither 
 this nor Hetherington's London Despatch the chief organ 
 of the moral-force party enjoyed the success of O'Con- 
 nor's organ, which was unrivalled in the history of popular 
 journalism. The very defects of the paper seemed to 
 drive it to the front. No bluster about the right of re- 
 volt could be talked by a quaking tiro in a village barn 
 but it was tricked out and belauded by the sensational 
 northern journal ; and the London Working-men's Asso- 
 ciation had the mortification of witnessing the perversion 
 of the popular press and the degradation of their demo- 
 cratic ideals. 
 
 Besides the journals named above, the chief Radical 
 newspapers were Henry Vincent's (unstamped) Western 
 Vindicator, published at Bath; the Northern Liberator,
 
 102 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 published at Newcastle; the True Scotsman, published 
 at Edinburgh; William Carpenter's Charter', and the 
 Cliampion, edited by the sons of William Cobbett. All 
 of these papers, in spite of occasional fiery articles, 
 advocated moral -force principles; but the deepening 
 distress of the time inclined the balance in favour of 
 more violent counsels. The connection between misery 
 and physical -force Chartism was seen not only in the 
 factory districts, where Oastler was hailed as "king", 
 but also in the metropolis. The silk-weavers of Spital- 
 fields, reduced to the verge of starvation by the decline 
 of their industry, offered promising materials for would- 
 be revolutionists, such as the uncompromising George 
 Julian Harney. This ardent young man, after suffering 
 three terms of imprisonment for his work in connection 
 with the free-press agitation, was now the life and soul 
 of the London Democratic Association, which soon num- 
 bered some 3000 members, drawn mainly from the suffer- 
 ing masses of East London. The wearing of the red cap 
 of liberty, and the words " Universal suffrage or death" 
 at the end of their documents, revealed their admiration 
 for the principles of Robespierre, and conveyed the hint 
 that even the methods of Marat might be applied to the 
 British bourgeoisie. 
 
 Another frank and fearless champion of a forcible 
 overthrow of government was Dr. John Taylor, perhaps 
 the ablest of the Scottish Chartists. Coming of a good 
 Ayrshire family, he had been trained for the medical 
 profession, which he had practised first in the navy, 
 and later at Glasgow. His bold sailor-like bearing and 
 affable manners, his manly appearance and fluent speech, 
 together with his honest indignation at the misery of the 
 poor, marked him out as one of the worthiest and most 
 popular of Chartist leaders. Lowery, once a tailor, was 
 one of the clearest and most convincing speakers: his 
 small and rather deformed figure seemed to plead for
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 103 
 
 the victims of the slop-shop and the sweater's den, and 
 presented a contrast to his mental gifts, which may 
 possibly have suggested to Kingsley the character of 
 Alton Locke. 
 
 It is impossible to describe in detail the local leaders. 
 Rider of Leeds, Marsden of Preston, Dr. M'Douall of 
 Ashton-under-Lyne, and Neesom of Bristol were promi- 
 nent advocates of physical force in the Chartist Conven- 
 tion, which now claims a brief notice. 
 
 Delegates from Chartist clubs or gatherings were 
 elected early in the year 1839 to form a Convention, 
 which was to draw up the petition for the Charter, and 
 discuss matters relating to the democratic cause. At 
 the first meetings of the Convention in London (Feb. 1839) 
 the schism in the Chartist ranks became apparent. The 
 sons of William Cobbett, acting along with Dr. Wade 
 and others, demanded that the work of the Convention 
 should cease with the presentation of the petition, a 
 half-hearted motion which was rejected mainly through 
 the vigorous oratory of O'Connor, Harney, and Marsden. 
 Thereupon three delegates from Birmingham, Dr. Wade, 
 and other Cobbettites successively withdrew from the 
 Convention. For various reasons this body now decided 
 to remove to Birmingham (May 13), a step which was to 
 increase the excitement already existing in the Midland 
 capital. Events which will presently be described served 
 to exasperate even the most law-abiding Chartists, and 
 elicited from one of the Scottish delegates to the Con- 
 vention the threat "We must shake our oppressors 
 well over hell's mouth, but we must not let them drop 
 in ". When such was the sentiment of a moral -force 
 Chartist, it seems surprising that the peace was preserved 
 at vast meetings held at Whitsuntide, in pursuance of 
 the advice of the Convention. The increasing schism in 
 that body seems to have suggested this device of throw- 
 ing the responsibility for future action on to the people,
 
 104 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 whose advice was to be sought on the following subjects: 
 withdrawal of money from banks, the advisability of a 
 "sacred month", of procuring arms, and of dealing 
 exclusively at "Chartist" shops. As might have been 
 expected from all signs of the times, the vast meetings 
 held at Kennington Common; Kearsall Moor, near 
 Manchester; Peep Green, in the West Riding of York- 
 shire; Glasgow; and among the miners of Monmouth- 
 shire, decided virtually in favour of the less prudent 
 course. 
 
 A slight acquaintance with human nature might have 
 warned the moral-force Chartists against an appeal to 
 mass meetings. Great are the perils of emotional oratory. 
 The speaker who appears to hold his audience spell-bound 
 is himself a victim to the subtle influence reflected from 
 a sea of upturned faces ; and the more potent the electric 
 current of sympathy necessary to oratorical success, the 
 more completely does the speaker merge his individuality 
 in the excited crowd which confronts him. Moreover, 
 the simultaneous meetings of Whitsuntide were held 
 shortly after the arrival of news from the West sufficient 
 to dash all hopes of a peaceful compromise. Vincent 
 had just been arrested at Newport. This does not appear 
 altogether to have been due to magisterial tyranny and 
 the selfish fears of shopkeepers. Vincent's conduct must 
 be held largely responsible for the collision. Once a 
 pillar of moral force, he had lately been lured on by his 
 sympathetic nature into excited harangues that endan- 
 gered the peace of the west country. The desire to be 
 in the forefront of the enthusiasts, always a mischievous 
 influence in times of excitement, had even led one of 
 Vincent's ardent supporters, a chemist of Trowbridge, 
 named Potts, to decorate his shop window with bullets 
 labelled Tory pills. 1 General alarm was caused in the 
 west by Vincent's oratory, and the authorities determined 
 
 1 Gammage, History of the Chartist Movement, p. 80 (edition of 1894).
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 105 
 
 to arrest him for a speech delivered at Newport, in which 
 he was reported to have exclaimed, "When the time for 
 resistance arrives, let your cry be, ' To your tents, O 
 Israel ' ". It is only fair to add that Vincent and his 
 friends denied any seditious intention in this speech, and 
 charged the magistrates with endeavouring- to provoke 
 a disturbance by his arrest. For the present the miners 
 of that county were held in check by the military; but 
 the news of Vincent's imprisonment aroused fierce in- 
 dignation, which subsequent events at Newport were to 
 intensify. 
 
 The exasperation caused by this news found vent in 
 the suggestions of O'Connor, Dr. Taylor, and others that 
 a run on the banks should be forthwith commenced, and 
 that a "sacred month" should be observed by all opera- 
 tives. The latter proposal, first proposed by the leveller 
 Benbow in 1831, and recently set to idyllic music by Mr. 
 Attwood, was now received with loud applause, though 
 a contemporary observer remarks that the artisans who, 
 amidst the excitement of meetings, cheered for the 
 month's holiday, were afterwards beset with misgivings 
 in their own homes. The proposal was really acceptable 
 only to the dupes who could not gauge its results, to 
 the knaves who desired civil war, and to hard-pressed 
 manufacturers who desired a temporary relief from the 
 burden of unremunerative wages. Indeed, its approval 
 by masters as a cure for over-production was so marked 
 as to enlighten some of the dupes; while the knaves 
 unmasked their own designs by suggesting that the 
 sacred month should be during harvest, thus leaving 
 the crops to the mercy of the elements. Lovett and 
 Bronterre O'Brien by persistent efforts succeeded in 
 postponing the acceptance of this proposal until after 
 the decision of Parliament as to the National Petition 
 for the Charter. 
 
 This document was of a legal and wholly unobjection-
 
 io6 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 able tenor, recommending the adoption by Parliament 
 of the "points" above named, with the exception of that 
 for equal electoral districts, which was now omitted. The 
 methods of the canvassers had in some cases, it is true, 
 been menacing, especially that of entering in a "black 
 book " the names of those who refused to support the 
 democratic cause; and the suggestion of the Northern 
 Star, that half a million of men armed with muskets 
 ought to escort the petition to Westminster, may well 
 have prejudiced Parliament against the petition. It was 
 perhaps also unfortunate that the document was pre- 
 sented (June 14, 1839) by Mr. Attwood, whose eccentri- 
 cities were undermining his influence both in Parliament 
 and in the country. The appearance of the National 
 Petition as a huge cylinder of parchment, rolled into the 
 House by stalwart backers, was also provocative of 
 mirth; but there was little if any of that contemptuous 
 behaviour which the Chartists believed to have been 
 shown towards their document. On the contrary, the 
 House suspended one of its standing orders, so as to 
 allow Mr. Attwood to make a speech concerning the 
 monster petition; and it fixed July 12 as the day for 
 hearing a detailed statement of the Chartist case. 
 
 But before that date arrived, events had happened 
 at Birmingham which further widened the breach 
 between Parliament and people. The Midland capital 
 had for some weeks been disturbed by Chartist meetings 
 held in one of the central points of that busy town. In 
 the open space near Nelson's statue, called the Bull 
 Ring, where bull-baiting had until recently ministered 
 to the athletic instincts of the Midlanders, the newer 
 democratic excitement had sought an outlet in the public 
 reading of the one weekly newspaper which Birmingham 
 could at that time support. After reading aloud the 
 Birmingham Journal to a crowd eager for news and 
 oratory, the reader gave his comments in forcible terms.
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 107 
 
 After a prohibition of these meetings by the mayor, they 
 were transferred for a time to other less central spots. 
 Nevertheless the local Chartist leaders, owing- to alleged 
 violent language, were arrested by "the two constables 
 of the town" assisted by "two police officers and two 
 of the town watchmen ". The growing excitement con- 
 vinced the mayor, Mr. Scholefield, that the disjointed 
 police force of the town would not suffice to put a stop 
 to the meetings in the Bull Ring, which were now de- 
 fiantly resumed. It was in vain that the mayor went in 
 person to that spot to beg the people not to assemble. 
 The magistrates, unable to compose the popular tumults, 
 applied to Lord John Russell for a contingent of London 
 police. On the arrival of the metropolitan constables 
 they were at once conveyed in omnibuses near to the 
 Bull Ring, and were ordered by the mayor and magi- 
 strates to disperse the crowd "quietly and temperately 
 but firmly and decidedly". Selecting from these self- 
 cancelling orders the rule of conduct most congenial to 
 themselves, the constabulary marched to the attack; 
 and, led though they were by the mayor, began to use 
 their truncheons on all who seemed inclined to dispute 
 their progress. After a moment's pause of sheer con- 
 sternation the crowd scattered in headlong flight. 
 Flushed with their triumph, the constables became sepa- 
 rated in the ardour of the pursuit, until they fell an easy 
 prey to the rallying populace. Chased now in their 
 turn, they took refuge in the Public Office, where they 
 remained until the arrival of the military released them 
 and cowed the rioters, who were beginning to tear down 
 the iron railings of St. Thomas' Church. 
 
 Such was July 4th the prelude to a far more serious 
 riot eleven days later. For in the meantime the over- 
 bearing conduct of the London police inflamed the wrath 
 of the townsfolk, which increased on the news of the 
 arrest of Dr. Taylor, Lovett, and Collins. Taylor's
 
 io8 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 crime was his alleged participation in the riot, though 
 he interfered at the end only to prevent the maltreat- 
 ment of the police by the victorious mob. The crime of 
 Lovett and Collins was the signature of the protest 
 drawn up by the National Convention against the 
 conduct of the police and the arrest of Dr. Taylor. Far 
 more serious, however, was the provocation given to 
 the people by the decisive refusal of Parliament (July 12) 
 even to consider the National Petition for the Charter. 
 Lord John Russell denied that the electorate needed any 
 expansion, and that there was much misery in the land ; 
 while he declaimed against the Chartists as promoting 
 disorder with a view to the equal division of property. 
 After this rebuff an outburst of indignation was almost 
 inevitable. 
 
 Still, there seemed to be few signs of a riot at 5 P.M. 
 on July 15, when the mayor left the Public Office for his 
 villa at Edgbaston. A crowd of men and boys had, it 
 is true, assembled at Holloway Head, attracted by a 
 suspicious notice that Mr. Attwood, the Radical member 
 for Birmingham, would address them there. As Att- 
 wood was then in London, this was obviously a device 
 for drawing together a crowd to hear their member's 
 account of his reception by the House of Commons. 
 Disappointed by Attwood's non-arrival, the Chartists 
 marched in procession through the town, along the 
 Warwick road, to meet Lovett and Collins, who, having 
 found bail, had just been released from the county 
 prison. Linking arm in arm, the Radicals marched in 
 orderly ranks through the Bull Ring, and were proceed- 
 ing towards the Warwick road, when news followed 
 that the London police were maltreating people in the 
 Bull Ring. The truth was that they had roughly ar- 
 rested a man who was reading aloud from a newspaper, 
 and that his auditors had forcibly rescued him. This 
 news was the spark which set Birmingham in a blaze.
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 109 
 
 At once the procession turned back for vengeance on the 
 hated policemen before their expected return to London. 
 Even now, appeals to the good sense of the crowd were 
 not wanting; but they were lost on the more inflammable 
 spirits, who, overpowering the police, kept them cooped 
 up in the Public Office. The demons of class hatred, 
 riot, plunder, were now let loose. Gangs of youths 
 began to march into the neighbouring streets, breaking 
 open the shops and scattering about their goods. The 
 sight of the smashed shutters and strewn linen of a 
 draper's shop suggested a bonfire, and soon an enormous 
 fire was blazing in front of Nelson's statue, whence 
 brands were forthwith plucked to fire any dwelling as 
 private malice or blind love of destruction dictated. The 
 latter impulse certainly was uppermost; for most of the 
 incendiaries were mere lads, one who fired a chemist's 
 shop being a shoeless ragged urchin. Where were the 
 stalwart London constables in the meantime? Held 
 in reserve in the Public Office until the arrival of two 
 magistrates to read the Riot Act. And the mayor and 
 magistrates? Were at home in the suburbs, ignorant 
 of the pandaemonium in the Bull Ring. The one magi- 
 strate who did arrive judged that the mob was too large 
 and fierce to quell until the soldiers came up. At last 
 the cumbrous legal machinery got the redcoats and blue- 
 coats to work; and their action speedily dispersed the 
 rioters, the thieves being now glutted with plunder, 
 while the hobbledehoys slunk away, alarmed at the 
 results of their own temerity. The destruction was, 
 indeed, considerable, amounting to some ^40,000 or 
 ^50,000. Yet the committee of the town -council 
 which was charged to report on these events asserted 
 the damage to be less than that caused by the ultra- 
 loyalists of Birmingham in the Priestley riots of 1792; 
 and they ended their investigation (to which I am mainly 
 indebted for the foregoing account) with a protest
 
 no The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 against their town being forthwith burdened by a new 
 constabulary force dependent on the government, and 
 therefore "insulting to the people of Birmingham, and 
 dangerous to the municipal rights and liberties of the 
 country at large". 1 Irritation against the new central- 
 ized system of police may perhaps have biased the judg- 
 ment of the committee; but all the evidence seems to 
 convict the London police of overbearing conduct, and 
 gives some colour to the arguments of Chartists that 
 the government sought to provoke them to deeds of 
 violence. On the other hand, the Duke of Wellington 
 sought to make party capital out of the occurrence by 
 taunting the government with having done nothing to 
 prevent disorder in Birmingham ; and he further merged 
 the statesman in the partisan by making (on newspaper 
 evidence) an assertion which sounded strangely on the 
 lips of the victor of Badajoz, that the state of Birming- 
 ham after the Chartist riots was worse than that of a 
 city taken by storm. 
 
 The facts of the case, when stripped of the exaggera- 
 tion of partisans or alarmists, appear to be these : that 
 the government did either too much or too little ; either 
 they should have sent an overwhelming force of soldiers 
 or police, or they should have counselled the use of the 
 most conciliatory methods. As for the local authorities, 
 they seem open to censure for lack of foresight and 
 preparation at a time when the rejection of the Charter 
 by Parliament portended a renewal of conflict with the 
 
 1 Russell's Police Bill of 1839, as modified at Peel's suggestion, em- 
 powered any town to raise and support a local police, subject, however, to 
 the general control of commissioners, who had similar powers over the 
 county police raised by county magistrates. The events of 1839, then, 
 hurried on the formation of a police force, which was rendered compulsory 
 and therefore universal by the act of 1856. It should be added that owing 
 to the protests of the men of Birmingham, led by Joseph Sturge, the 
 original proposals for subjecting the police force to a central commissioner 
 were so far modified as to leave the chief control to local elective authorities. 
 See Memoirs of J. Sturge, ch. 12.
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. in 
 
 detested London police. An official inquiry, however, 
 exonerated them from blame; and it is clear that the 
 events of July 15, far from being organized, were unex- 
 pected, and may even be classed as fortuitous. 
 
 The real sufferers were not the Birmingham trades- 
 men, nor even the rate-payers in the "hundred of 
 Hemlingford ", who had to pay their damages, but the 
 Chartists themselves. The previous disturbances at 
 Birmingham, together with riots at Llanidloes, seemed 
 to give colour to the assertions of Lord John Russell, 
 and of Whig and Tory newspapers, that Chartists were 
 mere sedition-mongers. It was in vain that the Chartist 
 Convention, on the motion of Bronterre O'Brien, ex- 
 pressed its disapproval of the insane project of a "sacred 
 month" (Aug. 6), and urged the use only of constitu- 
 tional methods. Repression and imprisonment were 
 now the order of the day. At Warwick, Lovett and 
 Collins were sentenced to a year's imprisonment. The 
 same sentence was meted out to Vincent at Newport. 
 Many others, including Bronterre O'Brien, were harshly 
 punished; while O'Connor, perhaps the most seditious 
 of all, was released from detention on suspiciously 
 small bail. Thinned by defections or arrests, and 
 weakened still more by internal dissensions, the first 
 Chartist Convention declared its dissolution on Sept. 6, 
 1839. 
 
 The first genuinely democratic assembly which had 
 met on English soil for centuries displayed many of the 
 best, but also some of the weaker, political qualities of 
 our race a sturdy belief in the ultimately healing effect 
 of liberty and in the ability of overwrought operatives 
 to use that precious boon without abusing it, an equally 
 persistent determination to abide by the laws if the law- 
 makers showed fair-play, and a certain dogged patience 
 amidst depressing and occasionally exasperating circum- 
 stances which few peoples are wont to evince. But
 
 ii2 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 along with these good qualities was to be seen that 
 proneness to faction and schism which hinders Britons 
 from effective organization, and defers the triumph of 
 democracy to a time when firmer cohesion has been 
 learnt in the school of adversity. And yet a comparison 
 of the debates in the Convention with those of the House 
 of Commons in the summer of 1839, so far from dis- 
 crediting the Chartist cause, will show why the demo- 
 cratic claims, when freed from the suspicions which then 
 naturally attached to them, have in our own days re- 
 ceived almost complete recognition. 
 
 It is unnecessary to follow in similar detail the events 
 of 1839-1841, which further exasperated the Chartists; 
 but a brief notice must be given to the outbreak at 
 Newport on Nov. 1839, if only from the fact of its being 
 the last serious collision which has occurred between 
 the people and the authorities in England. The arrest 
 of Henry Vincent, and his harsh treatment as a common 
 felon in Monmouth jail, had aroused fierce resentment 
 among the miners, who had often hung on the words 
 of "the Chartist Demosthenes". Appeals, which re- 
 ceived the support of Lord Brougham, were made, and 
 with some slight success, in favour of more lenient 
 treatment. Prominent among those who made the 
 appeals was a tradesman and magistrate of Newport 
 named Frost. For his vehement Chartist speeches Lord 
 John Russell had recently dismissed him from the magis- 
 tracy, an act against which his fellow-citizens protested. 
 Smarting under his own and his party's wrongs, Frost 
 planned with the miners of his county a great armed 
 demonstration for the release of Vincent and other pri- 
 soners. The miners, some armed with muskets, others 
 with pickaxes or iron-tipped sticks, were to have seized 
 Newport in the dead of night. But the heavy rain and 
 miry roads damped the ardour of very many and delayed 
 the march of the most determined, so that the autho-
 
 The Physical-Force Chartists. 113 
 
 rities were able hastily to dispose thirty soldiers and 
 several special constables in an hotel which then stood 
 in a commanding' position in the town. As the miners, 
 numbering some thousands, began to flood the space 
 in front of the hotel, the mayor summoned them to 
 disperse, and on their refusal read the Riot Act. The 
 shutters were then thrown open for the soldiers to reply 
 to the dropping shots now directed against the building". 
 Three volleys killed twenty Chartists, besides wounding 
 many more; and the rioters fled in confusion. 
 
 In the trial of Frost and his accomplices for high 
 treason, it was stated upon oath by one witness that 
 the ringleaders had planned to stop the mail-coach for 
 Birmingham, and that its non-arrival there was to serve 
 as a signal for a general revolt through the Midlands 
 and North. This story, which constituted a grave charge 
 of high treason, had gained general credence, though 
 upon slender evidence. Its flimsiness was skilfully 
 demonstrated by the able counsel for the defence, who 
 reminded the jury that the Newport mail -bags were 
 always ferried across the Severn to join the mail-coach, 
 which would in any case run from Bristol to Birming- 
 ham. The evidence was not absolutely decisive of the 
 charge that Frost, Williams, and Jones led the mob wit- 
 tingly to attack the soldiers. The charge of high treason 
 was, however, held to be made good at law; and for 
 nearly the last time a British court of justice heard the 
 awful doom awaiting a traitor, of being drawn on a 
 hurdle to the scaffold, there to be hanged and decapi- 
 tated (Jan. 1840). The commutation of this brutal 
 sentence to transportation for life was one of the un- 
 happily few exhibitions of mercy towards men rendered 
 desperate by their wrongs; and the whole policy of the 
 government further envenomed the feelings of millions 
 of Radicals during the months of hopeless misery that 
 followed. Despair settled down not only on our artisans, 
 
 (M416) H
 
 ii4 The Rise f Democracy. 
 
 but on our thinkers. " The state of society in England", 
 wrote Dr. Arnold to Thomas Carlyle in Jan., 1840, "was 
 never yet paralleled in history." And the seer of Chelsea 
 prefaced his epoch-marking 1 work, CJiartism, with the 
 warning that the essence of Chartism had not been put 
 down: "The matter of Chartism is weighty, deep- 
 rooted, far-extending; did not begin yesterday; will by 
 no means end this day or to-morrow". 
 
 Chapter VIII. 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 
 
 It is a well-known fact that a beaten crew always 
 consoles itself by quarrelling. The feather-weights, 
 accused of weakness and scratchiness, retaliate by 
 accusing ponderous number five of being an expensive 
 passenger; while all agree that stroke was irregular 
 and "cox" steered wildly. 
 
 As in aquatics, so in politics, failure sows broad- 
 cast a plentiful crop of suspicions and recriminations. 
 Charges of folly against the headstrong are met by 
 taunts of cowardice or bribery flung at the prudent; and 
 after the war of ink and mud has ceased, those are 
 seen to be the least bespattered who have flung most 
 assiduously. Truth herself meanwhile retires to a safe 
 distance; and the prudent historian generally imitates 
 the action of his guiding deity, hopeless of discerning 
 fact amid the wordy war. He notes, however, that 
 prudence and moderation are for the time overborne by 
 the stalwarts, who by the success of their own verbosity 
 are lured still further on their dangerous path. 
 
 Such was the general condition of the Chartist 
 movement in and after 1840. The mutual distrust of
 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 115 
 
 leaders and followers, the conflicts between "moral 
 force" and "physical force", were more damaging to the 
 cause than all the repressive measures of government. 
 They argued a mental unfitness to manage the affairs 
 of the party, still more, therefore, the affairs of the 
 whole nation. Enlightened Radicals mourned over the 
 schisms, and many of them discerned the cause to be a 
 lack of any effective education. Their judgment was 
 correct. It is ignorance which isolates men, keeping 
 each individual pot-bound by his own notions and pre- 
 judices and therefore unable or unwilling to merge his 
 will in the collective will, save under the pressure of 
 force. Ignorance, accordingly, though the best ally of 
 despotism, is the deadliest foe of democracy. 
 
 Perhaps there is one mental state which is rather 
 more mischievous than complete ignorance, viz. the first 
 glimmer of knowledge which in shallow natures begets 
 conceit; for then the mind, newly awakened by news- 
 paper articles or heated club rhetoric, clings to its shred 
 of truth as if it were the whole truth. Such was the 
 perilous position of British democracy in the Chartist 
 times. The occasion called for a Socrates to teach men 
 the eternal truth that the first step towards wisdom is 
 the consciousness of ignorance. It found the teacher 
 in Thomas Carlyle, who in varied cadences, from the 
 freshness and buoyancy of Past and Present (1843) to 
 the wail of despair which echoes through his Latter Day 
 Pamphlets, ceased not to teach the rich their responsi- 
 bilities, the idle the sacredness of labour, and the whole 
 people that they were "mostly fools". In more sym- 
 pathetic and therefore more telling words, the Rev. 
 Frederick Denison Maurice pleaded for national educa- 
 tion as the only means of securing a healthy and noble 
 existence for the people; and the increasing demand for 
 effective training of the popular intelligence led up to 
 the hapless Education Act of 1843 and to the further
 
 n6 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 efforts of Mr. Forster, a pupil of Carlyle, which were 
 crowned with success in 1870. 
 
 Not only among- the leaders of thought, but also 
 among- the more keen-sighted Chartists themselves, lack 
 of education was felt to be a fruitful cause of disunion. 
 Dr. Black, the founder of the London Working-men's 
 Association, had noted their intolerance of opposition, 
 and had endeavoured by educational agencies to pro- 
 mote a wider and more tolerant spirit. His pupil Lovett 
 amidst the schisms of 1839 realized the need of educa- 
 tion if Chartism was to succeed; and during- the term 
 of imprisonment which he spent with Collins in War- 
 wick jail he wrote, with some help from his fellow- 
 prisoner, a little book, Chartism, which pointed work- 
 ing-men to popular education as the necessary prepara- 
 tion for wiser action in the future. Alike spurning 
 and despairing- of any help from government, Lovett 
 proposed that the people should educate themselves 
 by a vast voluntary effort. The subscription of a 
 penny a week by every one who had signed the 
 national petition for the Charter would, he affirmed, 
 yield a fund sufficient to establish 80 "district halls" 
 and 710 circulating libraries, besides maintaining four 
 paid Chartist lecturers and distributing 20,000 political 
 tracts. The proposed education was of course to lead 
 up to definite political results, by undermining the old 
 edifice of privilege and rearing on firm foundations the 
 new structure of democracy. Such was Lovett's new 
 programme an English and more practical version of 
 the programme of education and insurrection which 
 Mazzini had ten years before sketched for his associa- 
 tion of Young Italy. 
 
 Meanwhile other Chartist leaders, while debarred by 
 prison walls from joining in the disputes of their sub- 
 alterns, were devising schemes which further divided 
 their already distracted followers. Henry Vincent, now
 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 117 
 
 cured of his physical-force leaning's, saw no hope for 
 Chartists unless they became teetotallers, whence he 
 and his followers were dubbed Teetotal Chartists by 
 Fearg-us O'Connor, and were denounced as trailing- a 
 red-herring 1 across the path of Radical reform. For the 
 same cause the Northern Star sneered at Lovett's edu- 
 cational efforts as "Knowledge Chartism"; while it 
 reprobated as mere Christian Chartism an interesting 
 effort of Scottish Radicals to combine political propa- 
 ganda with religious services in a sort of Labour Church. 
 All these, O'Connor's newspaper asserted, were middle- 
 class traps to lead astray the true believers from the 
 narrow path leading up to the People's Charter. There 
 was much force in these objections; and had not O'Con- 
 nor himself commenced to trail red-herrings across the 
 path, his criticisms would have been fatal to Lovett, 
 Vincent, and all other rivals. In fact, O'Connor now 
 held a position of great power. After a brief term of 
 imprisonment in York Castle, he speedily regained the 
 popular favour which he had lost by blowing hot and 
 cold on the subject of the projected popular rising of 
 November, 1839. The sight of their favourite orator 
 dressed in a suit of workman's fustian effaced the memory 
 of his unavailing bluster, and again his fiery force swept 
 the mass of Radical working-men along in his train. 
 But while protesting against any deviation from the five 
 points of the Charter, and their cynosure the Northern 
 Star, O'Connor was advocating measures which were 
 equally provocative of discord. He and his numerous 
 supporters founded a National Charter Association, 
 including numerous affiliated clubs, for the purpose of 
 making the Charter the law of the land. But, as no 
 less an authority than Francis Place pointed out, the 
 plan of the association violated the old law against 
 "corresponding societies", which threatened all ad- 
 herents with transportation. The refusal of many
 
 n8 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 moral -force Chartists to join an illegal association 
 naturally exposed them to the taunt of cowardice, while 
 they could retort that the scheme was intended as a 
 means of ruining- the cause. Another plan of O'Connor 
 and his associates served still further to disunite the 
 Radical ranks. This was a "land scheme" for settling 
 labourers and their families in agricultural communities. 
 The success which finally attended some of these Char- 
 tist settlements sufficiently attests the feasibility of the 
 proposal. But at the outset it was open to the criticism 
 of being illegal, or at least of not being recognizable at 
 law, or offering protection to investors. The suspicion 
 which generally dogs the steps of the popularity-hunter 
 fastened on this glaring defect in the proposal; and 
 sinister motives were with much frankness ascribed as 
 the raison d'etre of the whole scheme. The objection 
 gained weight from the fact that co-operative associa- 
 tions were but feebly guarded by law from the frauds 
 of designing secretaries and treasurers, who not unfre- 
 quently bolted with all the available cash. 
 
 The third cause of schism was the inclusion in the 
 revised national petition for the Charter of a clause for 
 the repeal of the union between Great Britain and Ire- 
 land. Many Chartists, especially those in Scotland, and 
 the members of Lovett's new National Association, 
 warmly protested against the intrusion of so alien a 
 topic into the Chartist programme. Hence the national 
 petition for the Charter was signed by smaller numbers 
 in 1842 than in 1839. But there was another reason for 
 the decline of Chartism which commenced in 1842, and 
 that was the competition of the Complete- Suffrage 
 Movement, which will always be associated with the 
 name of Joseph Sturge. 
 
 Joseph Sturge was born in 1793. He came of an old 
 Quaker family which maintained the tenets and practices 
 of that benevolent society with the quiet tenacity that
 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 119 
 
 has enabled the meek, first to weary out their perse- 
 cutors, and, in these later times, to inherit the earth. 
 As a youth of twenty years of age, Joseph had borne 
 testimony to his horror of all means of compulsion, 
 especially when designed for warlike ends. When drawn 
 for the militia, he allowed the sheep of his farm to be 
 driven off in payment of the fine for refusal to serve. 
 Turning subsequently to the corn trade, he settled at 
 Birmingham, where his unswerving integrity and massive 
 simplicity of character won general respect. After 
 taking a prominent share in the emancipation movement, 
 he was drawn more closely into political life by the 
 Birmingham riots of 1839, when he firmly protested 
 against the conduct of the London constables and the 
 proposal of a centralized police force. The contrast 
 between the sufferings of the masses and the general 
 apathy of Whigs and Tories served to convince him of 
 the need for a far completer act of enfranchisement than 
 that accorded by the measure of 1832. In 1841 he 
 wrote to Mr. Cobden " I have been driven to the con- 
 clusion that it is not only hopeless to expect justice for 
 the labouring population from the representatives of the 
 present constituencies, but that the infatuated policy 
 which now guides our rulers will be persisted in until 
 they plunge millions into want and misery". The "in- 
 fatuated policy", of course, was the support more or less 
 completely accorded by both the historic parties to the 
 corn-laws. But Sturge had in view much more than the 
 cheapening of bread : he declared that patriotism and 
 Christianity alike required men to strive by all peaceable 
 and legitimate means to remove "the enormous evil of 
 class legislation". As he had striven for the emancipa- 
 tion of black slaves in our colonies, so now his heart 
 went out to the white slaves who were at the mercy of 
 industrial conditions and economic laws that seemed to 
 be inexorable. But could not the power of the collective
 
 120 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 will mitigate those conditions and deflect those laws? 
 Above all, did not religious principle require the effort? 
 " It is a beautiful and distinguishing feature of Christi- 
 anity (he wrote) that it leads us to recognize every coun- 
 try as our country, and every man as our brother; and 
 as there is no moral degradation so awful, no physical 
 misery so great as that inflicted by personal slavery, I 
 have felt it my duty to labour for its universal extinction." 
 His first public avowal of sympathy with the Chartist 
 demands was at the close of a meeting of the Anti- 
 Corn-law League held at Manchester in November, 
 1841, when he invited the delegates to remain behind 
 for the discussion of a plan of Radical reform, based 
 on universal suffrage. The keen interest evinced at this 
 informal meeting proved not only the respect felt for 
 the proposer, but also the general conviction of the 
 Free-traders of the need of union with the working- 
 classes. Hitherto the league had found the opposition 
 of Chartist working-men to be fully as formidable as 
 that of landlords and farmers. Countless meetings 
 had been disturbed or broken up by the champions of 
 the Charter, who never tired of declaiming against free- 
 trade as another middle-class trick. In his interesting 
 Autobiography, Thomas Cooper has recorded the impres- 
 sion, resulting in his conversion to Chartism, produced 
 by a Chartist lecturer at Leicester, who thus declaimed 
 against the Cobdenites "Don't be deceived by the 
 middle classes again. You helped them to get their 
 votes. But where are the fine promises they made 
 you? . . . Municipal reform has been for their benefit, 
 not for yours ; and so with all their other reforms. And 
 now they want to get the Corn-laws repealed not for 
 your benefit, but for their own. 'Cheap bread', they 
 cry: but they mean 'Low wages'. Don't listen to their 
 cant and humbug. Stick to your Charter. You are 
 slaves without your votes."
 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 121 
 
 A strict sense of Christian duty and a desire to recon- 
 cile two important movements, the collisions between 
 which had been fatal to both, impelled Joseph Sturge to 
 proceed with his complete-suffrage agitation ; and in the 
 closing- days of 1841 he and other Cobdenites issued the 
 programme which marks the first organized attempt to 
 remove the suspicions and hatred separating the middle 
 and working classes during the past seven years. If for 
 no other reason, the work of the Complete -Suffrage 
 Association, founded at Birmingham early in 1842, de- 
 serves careful attention. As long as suspicions were 
 nursed by bourgeois and operatives, their agitations for 
 cheap bread and the Charter could not gain that irre- 
 sistible momentum which had carried the Reform Bill 
 of 1832, and was destined to gain the Reform Act of 
 1884. Lacking the support of most factory workers, 
 the Free-traders could hardly hope for success; while 
 the Chartists, spurning the advice of men of light and 
 leading, were in danger of following will-o'-the-wisps 
 into mazes of faction or bottomless bogs of intrigue. 
 
 The aim of Joseph Sturge and his associates was to 
 adopt all the fundamentals of Chartism, while dispens- 
 ing with compromising leaders and their objectionable 
 methods. Above all, the claim for universal suffrage 
 must be based on constitutional grounds, and urged 
 with reason. Here, indeed, they had a strong case. 
 Before Sir Robert Peel commenced the much-needed 
 reform of our finances, a great part of the taxation was 
 borne by the working-classes in the enhanced price of 
 the necessaries of life. The Complete -Suffrage Asso- 
 ciation could therefore urge with much force that a 
 fundamental principle of our constitution was violated 
 by the exclusion of a majority of those classes from the 
 parliamentary franchise. 1 They quoted Blackstone's 
 
 1 In a remarkable series of articles in the Nonconformist, which he had 
 just founded, Mr. Edward Miall dwelt strongly on this very practical griev-
 
 i2 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 assertion that "no subject of England can be constrained 
 to pay any aids or taxes, even for the defence of the 
 realm or the support of the government, but such as are 
 imposed by his own consent or that of his representa- 
 tives in Parliament". Appealing to this well-known 
 principle, the new association summoned to Birming- 
 ham popularly elected delegates to draw up the pro- 
 gramme. Bourgeois and artisan delegates came in about 
 equal numbers. During four days they deplored the 
 mistakes and discords of the past, and finally, with 
 shouts of joy and tears of emotion, carried proposals 
 which practically embodied the ( original ) People's 
 Charter. 
 
 For a time the alliance between the Sturgeites and 
 Chartists seemed to be complete ; and at a by-election at 
 Nottingham the Quaker advocate of peace and progress 
 had the embarrassing support of O'Connor's brazen voice 
 and redoubtable fists. The election was in many ways 
 remarkable. In the preceding general election of July 
 1841 one of the successful Whig candidates was known 
 to have used bribery so wholesale and barefaced that 
 the mere threat of legal proceedings procured his speedy 
 retirement in favour of his Tory opponent, Mr. Walter 
 of the Times. To spoil this game of battledore and 
 shuttlecock between the two historic parties, the Radicals 
 put forward Mr. Sturge as candidate. Like a fresh north 
 wind blowing upon miasma came Sturge's incisive 
 
 ance: "The poor are almost wholly unprotected. They are taxed more 
 heavily than any other class. Law, accessible to others, is of small avail to 
 them. The fruits of their toil are wrested from them, and industry and skill, 
 their only property, taken from them to augment the boundless wealth of 
 the landlords." Miall proposed to exclude from the franchise aliens, minors, 
 paupers, and all who had been convicted of crime. Referring to the alleged 
 corruptibility of the masses, he maintained that we never had had an honest 
 electorate, and that manhood suffrage would make bribery almost impos- 
 sible ! His attempt to refute the contention that education should precede 
 the grant of the franchise was equally inconclusive. (See Life of Edward 
 Miall, ch. 5.)
 
 The Complete -Suffrage Movement. 123 
 
 declaration that he would stand for Nottingham pro- 
 vided that no money was spent and no improper influence 
 used to bias a single voter in his favour. For the first 
 time a candidate was bold enough to declare that he 
 would not spend a sixpence on his election, and would 
 dispense with banners, processions, personal canvass, 
 and public-house support. Perhaps the novelty of this 
 declaration appealed as powerfully as its moral courage 
 to the popular sympathy, which was strongly evoked. 
 Thus, when the terrible "Tory lambs" of Nottingham 
 attempted a rush against the people's favourite, they 
 were met and routed by a charge of Feargus O'Connor, 
 Thomas Cooper, and other Chartists, which sent the 
 Rev. Rayner Stephens in headlong flight from the Tory 
 hustings. In the end Sturge was defeated by a slender 
 majority, but an election petition having unseated Mr. 
 Walter, another complete -suffrage candidate was re- 
 turned for Nottingham. 
 
 Meanwhile in the House of Commons itself events 
 were happening which favoured the champions of 
 reform. The disclosures effected by Mr. Roebuck's 
 "Elections' Compromise Committee" convinced many 
 members that little was to be hoped from the existing 
 electoral system. 
 
 But the Radical movement, while forging ahead, was 
 suddenly checked by the terrible strikes of the summer 
 of 1842. With wheat at sixty-five shillings the quarter, 
 and work and wages declining, the misery of our 
 operatives was a direct incentive to violent outbreaks. 
 The increasing power of the trade-unions determined 
 the direction of the popular discontent towards strikes, 
 which spread through the Midlands and North amid 
 scenes of reckless violence. Originating in some petty 
 tyrannies of Staffordshire masters, the movement be- 
 came almost a labour war; and bands of operatives 
 marched about, compelling mills to stop work, and in
 
 124 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 some cases smashing- the machinery, or pulling the 
 plugs from reservoirs. In the Potteries, at Stockport, 
 Blackburn, and Preston, there was serious rioting; and 
 the physical-force Chartists, with overweening contempt 
 of the "moral-force humbugs", boasted that, having 
 stopped every manufactory within fifty miles of Man- 
 chester, the men were masters of the situation. The 
 determined action of the authorities, the conciliatory 
 attitude of several masters, and the ingathering of a 
 bounteous harvest, served speedily to restore order to 
 the country, prosperity to trade, and comfort to the 
 home ; but the work of class reconciliation was seriously 
 hindered by the plug riots, the consequent arrests, and 
 the silly charges that the Cobdenites had instigated the 
 acts of violence. 
 
 The results of the breach of confidence were seen in 
 a conference between the "complete suffragists " and 
 the Chartists held at Birmingham in Dec. 1842. The 
 question was now more than ever one of men, not of 
 measures. Though the programmes were substantially 
 the same, the differences between tweedledum and 
 tweedledee were hotly discussed. Even Lovett declared 
 that he would never surrender the name of the People's 
 Charter for that of Complete Suffrage; while one of 
 Sturge's followers excited the wrath of the O'Connorites 
 by the frank assertion that his party adopted Chartist 
 principles but objected to Chartist leaders. Eventually 
 the name of the Charter was retained; whereupon the 
 Sturgeites withdrew from all association with a political 
 party led by men, or rather by a man, whom they could 
 not respect. 
 
 Their judgment as to the fate of the party if cham- 
 pioned by O'Connor was amply justified. Owing to 
 personal feuds, the remaining Chartist delegates speedily 
 dwindled from more than three hundred to thirty-seven, 
 who squabbled about the details of O'Connor's land
 
 The Complete- Suffrage Movement. 125 
 
 scheme. The chiefs acrimony towards all who differed 
 from him found vent in diatribes against his former 
 devotee, Thomas Cooper, even during the two years' 
 imprisonment which the Leicester leader suffered for 
 his share in the recent disturbances. On the whole, 
 Cooper was the gainer. O'Connor thenceforth lost the 
 aid of his ablest remaining supporter; while Cooper, 
 after composing in prison his remarkable poem, the 
 Purgatory of Suicides, dedicated his great abilities almost 
 solely to the cause of popular education, sharing with 
 Henry Vincent the honours of the platform. As these 
 two men lived mainly on the funds supplied by middle- 
 class audiences, they were speedily scouted as renegades 
 by the Chartist irreconcilables, and ceased to take any 
 very active part in the movement. 
 
 Apparently, then, class jealousy was more powerful 
 than all the efforts at conciliation; and the secret or 
 openly expressed desires of the working-men levellers 
 were too strong to admit any thorough co-operation 
 with middle-class democrats like Joseph Sturge, who 
 sought parliamentary reform only for the redress of the 
 more glaring grievances of the age. But his efforts 
 were not to be fruitless. Soured though they were by 
 the disappointments of the year, Chartist working-men 
 could not forget that the olive branch had been held out 
 by prosperous business men like Sturge, Bright, and 
 Cobden ; and the reviving trade and prosperity of the 
 next years reminded all keen-sighted artisans of the 
 unity of interests which binds together employers and 
 employed, and of the supreme importance of a just and 
 wise system of taxation. The lesson was not lost. 
 
 While the remaining Chartist leaders were damaging 
 their cause, the complete-suffrage party also lost ground. 
 Having failed to unite the artisans and middle classes 
 in a solid phalanx of reform, the Sturgeites began to be 
 reabsorbed by the Anti-Corn-law League from which
 
 126 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 they had emerged; and the defeat of Joseph Sturge at 
 Birmingham in a three-cornered contest decided him to 
 retire from active political life. His last sixteen years 
 were unceasingly devoted to the extinction of slavery 
 and the maintenance of peace principles. But his char- 
 acter and career told with effect far beyond these two 
 spheres of work. In an age distracted by fierce class 
 hatreds and a narrow devotion to the claims of party, 
 the influence of Joseph Sturge's simple, manly character 
 was distinctly elevating. His insistence on manhood 
 suffrage was ever based on an unswerving religious 
 belief, that only by treating every man as if he possessed 
 the germs of noble character, could the grand possibilities 
 of mankind be fitly developed. The intensity of this 
 faith has inspired the following reference in Whittier's 
 memorial lines 
 
 " Thanks for the good man's beautiful example, 
 
 Who in the vilest saw 
 Some sacred crypt or altar of a temple 
 Still vocal with God's law". 
 
 Joseph Sturge did not live to see even the first instal- 
 ment of democratic reform. He bequeathed his work 
 to others, especially to Edward Miall, who up to the 
 close of a long literary and parliamentary career strug- 
 gled for complete suffrage on the same lofty principles. 
 In 1851, when Carlyle's Latter Day Pamphlets gained 
 a great vogue for the theory that a beneficent des- 
 potism was the best of all governments, Miall flinched 
 not from attacking this "philosophy of the stick", even 
 when wielded by the redoubtable seer of Chelsea. In an 
 important public lecture he protested against the deter- 
 mined pessimism which regarded mankind as ever on 
 the down-grade, unless tugged upwards by some heaven- 
 sent genius. The need of this, as of all generations, 
 exclaimed Miall, was not external compulsion, even by
 
 The Complete-Suffrage Movement. 127 
 
 a hero, but rather internal improvement. " Heroes are 
 like stars, brilliant because the heavens are dark. Where 
 the ' masses ' are themselves enlightened and free, hero- 
 ism ceases ; and what would have shone forth effulgently 
 becomes unnoticeable when all around is daylight." 
 The chief moralizing" influence in the life of a people, as 
 in that of an individual, was not compulsion, but con- 
 fidence. A class previously degraded almost to a slave's 
 moral level could be restored to manliness and integrity 
 by a bestowal of trust, which always evoked nobler 
 feelings. As Rugby boys voted it a shame to lie to 
 Arnold because he utterly trusted them, so the like 
 feelings would, in course of time, be felt towards a 
 government which treated its subjects as responsible 
 citizens. "A higher system of government must be 
 developed one that relies less on laws and more on 
 principles, less on force and more on the good-will of 
 subjects. Safety will be found in the affectionate attach- 
 ment of contented citizens." 
 
 Such was Miall's effective, if not brilliant, reply to 
 Carlyle's vehement invectives against democracy. For 
 the present the complete-suffrage movement made little 
 headway, amid the material prosperity of the fifties and 
 the distractions caused by the Crimean War and the 
 Indian Mutiny. But, as will be shown in chapters XI. 
 and XIII., its aims were gradually to be realized after 
 the delay which generally overclouds the first roseate 
 hopes of speedy victory. In the interval an important 
 work of class reconciliation had been quietly progress- 
 ing, which, to all but Cassandra seers, robbed reform of 
 its earlier terrors. That reconciliation dates from the 
 year 1842, when the work of Joseph Sturge and Edward 
 Miall, and the material prosperity inaugurated by Sir 
 Robert Peel's financial reforms, began to assuage the 
 class hatreds of the past, to close the era of revolu- 
 tionary tumults, and to usher in a period of prolonged
 
 128 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 and peaceful progress unparalleled in the history of any 
 nation. 
 
 Chapter IX. 
 Revolution or Evolution? 
 
 It would be a refreshing change if some historian, 
 reluctantly tearing himself away from official reports 
 and diplomatic intrigues, would endeavour to gauge 
 the influence of national recreation on national character. 
 Possibly it is quite as potent as the struggles between 
 the ins and the outs or the manceuvrings of rival 
 diplomatists ; for while the Olympians are weaving their 
 mighty plans, the millions beneath are fashioning their 
 characters alike in hours of toil and of recreation. The 
 cafe, therefore, may claim the attention of the historical 
 student as well as the council-chamber, the restaurant 
 no less than the august debates of Westminster. How 
 much of the heaviness of Georgian life, and the conse- 
 quent stolidity of Georgian politics, was due to the full- 
 bodied wine of Oporto which every patriotic Briton felt 
 called upon to imbibe, to the exclusion of the wines of 
 hostile Gaul, which were accused of promoting fickleness 
 and instability? Who shall estimate the effect on the 
 German of his light Rhenish or equally light beer, as 
 contrasted with that of the heady ale drunk by his island 
 cousin? What end is there to the social and political 
 influence of the Continental cafe and the English ale- 
 house? The potations of the Frenchman and German, 
 even their quaflfings of coffee Lessing's "dear melan- 
 choly coffee which begets fancies" so far from besotting 
 the mind, actually favour the growth of thoughts; and 
 thought, if it clashes with the actual, is the mother of 
 revolution. In those countries, therefore, prosperity is 
 by no means a barrier to discontent, because it tends to
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 129 
 
 stimulate the growth of ideas. In England, on the 
 contrary, it has proved to be an infallible sedative from 
 the days of Walpole to our own, because the expenditure 
 of our lower classes then turns largely to a stimulant 
 which dulls the brain. Who ever heard of any serious 
 revolt concocted in an English ale-house? Is not that 
 the abode of political stability, where John Bull, so long 
 as he has money to spend, is wont to subside into thick- 
 skinned, fuddled contentment in the best of all possible 
 worlds? 
 
 The conditional clause is important. John Bull money- 
 less is the most persistent of malcontents, and even 
 evolves political principles always with an eye to future 
 business. But when blest with beef and beer, his ideas 
 are few, his contentment is colossal. 
 
 The history of English Radical reform therefore 
 centres around periods of commercial depression and 
 general misery, such as mark the almost unbroken series 
 of lean years succeeding the great war, the sharp pinch 
 of 1847-1848, the crash of 1866, and the long depression 
 of trade and agriculture which set in after 1876. In the 
 prosperous periods we have little to record except the 
 unheeded utterances of reformers crying in a wilderness 
 of plenty, or the quiet adoption by Conservatives of 
 measures which they had previously vetoed as revolu- 
 tionary. So complete is John Bull's faith in the steady- 
 ing effect of beef and beer. 
 
 The future of Chartism was mainly to be determined 
 by the economic condition of our working-classes, i.e. 
 by the general condition of our industries. If these 
 revived, and, consequently, if comfort replaced misery 
 in the homes of our operatives, the movement which 
 threatened to be revolutionary would naturally subside, 
 remaining merely as a quietly propelling force in the 
 direction of parliamentary reform. Such was the mo- 
 mentous "condition-of-England question" which claimed 
 
 (M416) I
 
 130 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 the attention of every thinking- man. Above all, Thomas 
 Carlyle had proved that Chartism was not solely a 
 political movement, but was quite as much a " knife and 
 fork question". It had long 1 been obvious that the 
 popular discontent was due mainly to low wages, 
 irregular work, and high prices; and some men had 
 perceived the tolerably obvious connection between bad 
 trade and the burdens of a stupid system of taxation. 
 In words which then seemed prophetic, William Cobbett 
 had foretold that the effect of the awful burdens be- 
 queathed by the great war would be to accelerate the 
 march of democracy by arousing indignation against the 
 policy which, after recklessly amassing the national debt, 
 allowed it to fetter the limbs of industry. The whole 
 course of the democratic movement in our land testified 
 to the accuracy of the surmise ; and it was not until Sir 
 Robert Peel readjusted the financial burdens that stability 
 was restored alike to our industries, our society, and our 
 institutions. 
 
 No statesman of this century has exerted so potent 
 an influence in harmonizing conflicting interests, and in 
 adapting party methods to new conditions, as Sir Robert 
 Peel. It was due very largely to his foresight and 
 common sense that the Tory party in 1841 came back to 
 power, only nine years after it appeared to have been for 
 ever extinguished by the first Reform Bill. The very 
 magnitude of that disaster had enabled Peel to broaden 
 the basis of the party by insisting that its mission thence- 
 forth was to rally the newly enfranchised, as far as 
 possible, to the support of our ancient institutions. His 
 followers accepted the situation with an adaptability born 
 of defeat, and enhanced by hope of future recovery ; and 
 the party which returned to power in 1841 had little in 
 common with the "ignorant and obstinate faction" 
 whose approaching overthrow Greville had, ten years 
 previously, hailed with satisfaction.
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 131 
 
 The newly styled Conservative party now dominated 
 the situation ; but, fortunately for its further usefulness, 
 Peel dominated the party, thereby continuing the educa- 
 tional process which his malicious detractor, Disraeli, 
 was subsequently to carry to unheard-of lengths. Peel's 
 mental endowments were curiously characteristic of the 
 sturdy Lancashire stock whence he sprang. The Peels 
 of Peel Fold, near Bury, were an honoured family of the 
 yeoman class ; but with all the toughness of the farmer, 
 the father of the statesman showed keen foresight and 
 business capacity in mortgaging his estate so as to em- 
 bark in the more profitable pursuit of calico-printing, 
 then in the heyday of its early prosperity. This change 
 from bucolic to mercantile pursuits curiously fore- 
 shadows the mental and political development of the 
 son, who was brought by stress of circumstances to 
 abandon nearly all the tenets of his early days. Begin- 
 ning his official career as a colleague of the Liverpools 
 and Castlereaghs, Sir Robert Peel was to end his days 
 as a convert to the Manchester school. The sincerity of 
 the change can be questioned only by pessimists, or by 
 cranks who rate rigid consistency above a nation's 
 anguish. Peel could resist tenaciously as long as his 
 political creed was undergirded by conviction ; but, that 
 gone, the antique framework of his mind gave way be- 
 neath the first exceptional strain. Even in 1842 Peel was 
 practically a Free-trader. In his famous budget speech of 
 that year he admitted the cogency of the arguments for 
 free exchange, striving, however, to mollify the Tory 
 squires by declaring that corn was an exception to the 
 general rule, owing to the danger of national depend- 
 ence on foreigners for food-supply. 
 
 Contenting himself with a reduction of the sliding-scale 
 duties on corn, he turned his attention to our complex 
 tariff, which certainly needed attention. It imposed 
 duties on some 1200 articles a system which was disas-
 
 132 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 trous to the nation's finance, and to the manufacturers and 
 operatives who formed the backbone of the nation. The 
 failure of Whig" financiers in 1837-41 to wring sufficient 
 funds out of a multitude of niggling little customs and 
 excise duties might well have convinced every observer 
 that our taxation had been inherently absurd. Readers 
 of Adam Smith knew that our fiscal system violated his 
 sound canon of finance, that the best form of taxation 
 was that which takes from the people as little as possible 
 over and above what it brings into the public treasury. 
 The lessons which students learnt from the father of 
 political economy had been borne in on manufacturers 
 by enormous stocks of unsaleable goods and on opera- 
 tives by the bitter experience of an empty larder. In- 
 deed the Radical clubs notably those of Leeds and 
 Birmingham had frequently petitioned for the repeal of 
 all taxes which pressed on the workers. Doubtless 
 Peel's action in substituting direct for indirect taxation 
 was dictated rather by regard for the maxims of political 
 economy than for the demands of Radical clubs; but 
 the constant preoccupation of his mind with the condi- 
 tion of our working-classes, which Guizot notes as his 
 dominant characteristic, may well have strengthened his 
 determination to recur to the policy adopted with such 
 wondrous results by the younger Pitt towards the close 
 of the eighteenth century. His inspiring appeal to the 
 House to revert to that potent fiscal instrument, the 
 income-tax, to which their forefathers had "submitted 
 with buoyant vigour and universal applause when 
 threatened by the might of revolutionary France ", was 
 conceived in the happiest spirit of Conservative oratory; 
 and yet its practical results were to be the gradual un- 
 dermining of that protective system of which Peel had 
 been the accredited champion. The imposition of an 
 income-tax of sevenpence in the , in place of a multi- 
 tude of customs and excise duties, was soon seen to be
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 133 
 
 a most beneficent experiment, restoring order to our 
 finances and prosperity to our languishing industries 
 and commerce. After a trial of three years, Peel per- 
 suaded his party to prolong the experiment for a similar 
 period; and let in 430 more articles duty free, besides 
 remitting the imposts on glass, cotton, wool, &c. The 
 increased prosperity of the country under the new 
 system had undermined Peel's belief in the expediency 
 of "protection" in any shape or form; but it was re- 
 served for the rain-storms of the autumn of 1845 to 
 inundate the last water-tight compartment of his brain. 
 When two millions of Irish were in risk of starvation, 
 he saw it to be not only a folly but a crime to hinder 
 the importation of cheap corn ; and millions, not only of 
 Irish, but also of Britons, soon blessed the statesman 
 who, at the sacrifice of consistency, gave the people 
 cheap bread. 1 
 
 With the details of these important fiscal changes we 
 are not here concerned, but rather with their results on 
 the people's welfare, and on that reconciliation between 
 the middle and lower classes which in 1842 seemed far 
 distant. After the beginning of the long war with 
 France the trend of prices had pressed heavily on our 
 people. In the years 1792-1813 the rise of prices, due 
 almost entirely to war, had been nearly 70 per cent; and, 
 despite a slight fall after the peace, the old level had 
 never been reached. 2 
 
 At the risk of repeating what has been previously 
 stated, a brief review of the operatives' position must 
 
 1 In the budget of 1846 Peel also admitted foreign sugar on the same 
 terms as colonial sugar, abolishing those preferential rates for free-grown 
 sugar on which the abolitionists had insisted. For an account of the Free 
 Trade struggle, see Free Trade and its Results, by G. Armitage Smith, 
 M.A., in this series. 
 
 3 Mr. Lowe in his Present State of England (1823) estimates the annual 
 expenses of a rural labourer's family of 5$ persons as follows: 1792, 27 ; 
 1813, j 4 8; 1823, 32.
 
 134 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 here be hazarded, if we would understand the magnitude 
 of the benefits wrought by the change. In the thirty 
 years succeeding the war, the workmen were victims to 
 almost every possible adverse circumstance. The factory 
 system was slowly grinding out hand-labour; and yet 
 the new wholesale methods could not produce their 
 natural and ultimately beneficial results of cheapening 
 commodities, owing to the dearness of raw materials. 
 The manufacturer, when pressed by foreign competition, 
 looked to the cheapening of labour as the natural set- 
 off to the dearness of his raw materials; and the vast 
 growth of our population gave him almost limitless 
 opportunities of effecting economies in his human ma- 
 chinery. The law did not as yet recognize trade- 
 unions; and the new facilities of migration opened up 
 by the Poor-law of 1834 and by railways, deluged the 
 market with unskilled labour. And while wages were 
 thus depressed with the tacit connivance of the legisla- 
 ture, the prices of the necessaries of life were raised by 
 a fiscal system which seemed devised so as to hamper 
 the energies of the trader and empty the larder of the 
 poor man. Such was the economic cause of the dis- 
 content which found vent in Chartism. 
 
 The removal of the irritant soon produced the natural 
 result. With cheap raw materials, and with industry 
 unhampered by the visits of the excise officer, commerce 
 began to forge ahead; and manufacturers soon dis- 
 covered that they reaped from the cheapness of raw 
 wool and cotton far greater benefit than from low wages, 
 which impaired the efficiency of the human machinery. 
 
 British workmen, however, were benefited not only 
 by increasing regularity of employment and a gradual 
 rise in wages, but by the cheapening of many necessaries 
 of life. The evidence on this subject collected by Mr. 
 David Chadwick is very striking. From careful in- 
 quiries made among the operatives of Lancashire, he
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 135 
 
 found that the average expenses of a working-man with 
 a wife and three children were as follows : 
 
 1839. 1849. 1859. 1887. 
 
 Bread, flour, &c., ... 7/6 5/8 5/4 4/8^ 
 
 Groceries, 7/9^ 6/1 # 5/11 4/3 
 
 Other items, such as butcher's -meat, clothes, and vege- 
 tables, showed very slight reductions, while rent and milk 
 increased. 1 But Mr. Chadwick adds his testimony to 
 those of many others as to the general improvement in the 
 material condition of operatives not only in Lancashire 
 but throughout Great Britain. The fact must be ad- 
 mitted by the most jaundiced croaker, if he will contrast 
 the present condition of Birmingham, Glasgow, and the 
 east end of London with that portrayed in the gloomy 
 pages of Karl Engel's Condition of the Labouring Classes 
 in England in 1844? 
 
 That gifted writer so far underestimated the effects of 
 Sir Robert Peel's economic reforms as confidently to 
 prophesy the imminence of a social revolution in Eng- 
 land. Certainly the outlook was still ominous. The 
 desperate strikes of 1842 were succeeded in 1844 by a 
 bitter struggle between masters and men in the northern 
 colliery districts, which left the men defeated but defiant, 
 and enrolled 30,000 of them as physical-force Chartists. 
 The year 1845 brought new troubles. It was the year 
 of the railway bubble and of the potato famine. Never 
 since the days of the South Sea Bubble did so much 
 money change hands on schemes so risky and baseless; 
 and had all the ^"600,000,000 of proposed capital been 
 
 1 For fuller details see Mr. D. Chadwick's papers read to the Statistical 
 Society in December, 1859, to the British Association in 1861 and in 1887. 
 He places the average increase of the wages of Lancashire operatives in the 
 period 1850-1883 as only 10 per cent. Others reckon the increase as 35 per 
 cent or even more. 
 
 2 In the preface to the 1892 edition of this able work, the author, while 
 still waving the red flag, admits that improvement had taken place, espe- 
 cially in the east of London,
 
 136 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 really subscribed, the collapse of most of the schemes 
 would have been a national disaster. As it was, the 
 for once over-imaginative bourgeoisie sustained terrible 
 losses; and that too in an autumn when the potato-rot 
 might have counselled prudence. The locking up of so 
 much money in railway enterprises, and the purchase 
 of vast supplies of foreign corn to feed the starving Irish 
 and make up the deficiency of the British food-supplies, 
 naturally produced a tightness of money which culmi- 
 nated in the financial crisis of 1847. Amidst the conse- 
 quent distress, which though temporary was severe, the 
 physical-force Chartists had their last chance of effecting 
 a forcible change in the constitution. The years 1847-48 
 are therefore of considerable interest. To superficial 
 observers it seemed that the current was again setting 
 in towards revolution, as it undoubtedly was on the 
 Continent. Or was the movement of the waters due 
 merely to winds which agitated the surface but left the 
 volume of the current still sweeping forward with un- 
 impeded force? 
 
 Judging from present signs, the United Kingdom was 
 in a perilous state. Ireland was palpitating with misery 
 and disaffection. In the general election of August, 
 1847, advanced Radicals secured several seats, Feargus 
 O'Connor gaining a conspicuous triumph at Nottingham. 
 In truth he was now at the height of his popularity, 
 owing to the successful floating of his land scheme for 
 the multiplication of cottier properties, and that too in 
 spite of the determined opposition of Cooper and many 
 other Chartists. In spite of discords among the leaders, 
 Chartism seemed to gain power over the unemployed, 
 even before the dawn of the year of revolutions which 
 seemed to promise a speedy victory for democracy all 
 along the line. 
 
 Man is a gregarious creature; and even though the 
 condition of England differed enormously, as will pre-
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 137 
 
 sently appear, from that of Italy, France, and Germany, 
 yet Chartism seemed to gain new aggressive force when 
 in the early months of 1848 news arrived of the over- 
 throw of most of the continental dynasties. First in 
 Sicily, then in other Italian cities oppressed by Austrian 
 or domestic tyranny, the torch of revolution flared up; 
 then, speeding over the Alps, it consumed what appeared 
 to be the most stable dynasty on the Continent, that of 
 the House of Orleans. In quick succession the flames 
 burst forth in the chief cities of Germany and Austria, 
 the famous repressive system of Metternich proving to 
 be merely a carefully planned " set piece", along which 
 the democratic powder fizzed and crackled with most 
 effect wherever the forces of tyranny had seemed to be 
 most overwhelming. These events naturally produced 
 a profound effect on English democratic opinion. When 
 Louis Philippe, King of the French, escaped out of 
 Paris in a cab; when Metternich, after controlling the 
 destinies of Central and Southern Europe, was fain to 
 flee from Vienna in a washerwoman's cart; when Italian 
 Dukes and German translucencies hastily granted demo- 
 cratic constitutions, to petition for which had recently 
 been a sure passport to the dungeon, could not a mon- 
 ster demonstration of the men of London force the 
 Charter on a trembling and penitent Parliament? Such 
 were the illusory hopes which produced the final re- 
 crudescence of physical-force Chartism and led up to 
 the fiasco of April 10. In England a cab was to be 
 the doom, not of the monarch, but of the Chartist 
 petition. 
 
 A kindly Providence hid this issue of events from the 
 gaze of the enthusiastic Radicals who planned the coer- 
 cion of Parliament. For a time the agitation proceeded 
 briskly, vast meetings being held on Blackheath and 
 Kennington Commons, as also at Peep Green in York- 
 shire, and at Oldham Edge. Once more a National
 
 138 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Petition for the People's Charter received myriads of 
 signatures, with significant hints that it was the last 
 that would be sent to the House ot Commons as at 
 present constituted. " If they reject this, we'll go to 
 work " such was the determination expressed in many 
 a town. Again delegates were elected to a National 
 Convention; and this people's parliament, which seemed 
 to threaten the august body at Westminster, assembled 
 in London on April 4th, 1848, to plan a vast demonstra- 
 tion on behalf of the Charter. April loth was the date 
 fixed for this event "ten days too late" was the sar- 
 castic comment of Sanders Mackay, who in Kingsley's 
 immortal story represents the best elements of moral- 
 force Chartism. 
 
 Meanwhile the authorities had not been idle. The 
 Duke of Wellington, entrusted with the command of 
 the troops garrisoning London, held large forces in 
 reserve, while others were massed at the Tower, the 
 Bank of England, and other points. Keeping most of 
 the troops out of sight, the authorities depended mainly 
 on the impression created by an overwhelming force 
 or special constables, of whom 150,000 or more were 
 enrolled. Among them was Prince Louis Napoleon, 
 who, before that mad year had run its course, was to 
 leap on the shoulders of the French democracy as Prince 
 President of the French Republic. 
 
 In our land the government was strong enough to 
 resist the forcible encroachments of the mob, or the 
 insidious assaults of the "heir to the revolution". In 
 France the Orleans dynasty received no active support 
 from the middle classes, the upper stratum of which only 
 enjoyed electoral rights; and it met with a dogged resist- 
 ance from the artisans, whose claims it had persistently 
 disregarded. In England, on the other hand, the middle 
 classes had been pacified by the abolition of the Corn- 
 laws; and their spokesmen, Cobden and Bright, at the
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 139 
 
 last meeting- of the famous League, had expressed not 
 only their devotion to the crown, but even a mild ap- 
 proval of the action of the House of Lords in ratifying 
 the verdict of the House of Commons. "Above all," 
 said John Bright, in a passage which evoked loud cheers, 
 "the people have learned that the way to freedom is 
 henceforward not through violence and bloodshed." The 
 working-classes in England had yet one more illustration 
 of this important truth in the peaceful victory which 
 crowned the efforts of Mr. Fielden and Lord Shaftesbury 
 to reduce the hours of factory work to ten a day for 
 women and young persons a change which was to take 
 effect on May i, 1848. When two such boons as cheap 
 bread and shorter hours of labour were peacefully ob- 
 tained from Parliament, what need was there forcibly to 
 change its composition? The lessons of the past and 
 present obviously counselled prudence and patience. To 
 this cause, and not to any inherent difference in the 
 nature of the peoples themselves, are we to attribute the 
 self-restraint of London artisans in 1848, as contrasted 
 with the vehemence of their brethren in Italy, France, 
 and Germany. When the more reckless of the Chartists 
 boasted of the imminent overthrow of the British govern- 
 ment, they ranted to artisans who were mainly apathetic; 
 while a sprinkling of zealots, along with hobbledehoys 
 and thieves, alone cheered for the coming revolution. As 
 for the threats of French and Irish assistance, nothing 
 tended more to send sensible workmen to their homes, 
 and bring into the streets every householder to serve as 
 a special constable ; so that physical-force Chartism, at 
 the crisis, found itself confronted by a crushing supe- 
 riority of force. This was the dominant fact of the 
 situation on April 10. 
 
 Another item in the programme also portended, not 
 tragedy, but burlesque. Feargus O'Connor, as has been 
 previously noted, amid all his apparently reckless rhetoric
 
 140 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 about death or glory, took care to intersperse numerous 
 saving clauses ; and by many of his former partisans he 
 had already been charged with cowardice for not acting 
 up to the level of his inflammatory harangues. He could, 
 however, assert in his own defence that he had never 
 really advised revolt if it appeared hopeless; and now, 
 when the government privately intimated that a monster 
 procession to Westminster would be resisted, he prepared 
 to cover his retreat by a well-worn device, a display of 
 oratorical squibs. Conscious of impending failure, 
 O'Connor and some other prominent delegates, among 
 whom were Ernest Jones and Julian Harney, stepped 
 into the triumphal car, which, with another gaily-decked 
 chariot conveying the monster petition, headed the pro- 
 cession. Filing along through the city, and over Black- 
 friars Bridge, the petitioners arrived at Kennington 
 Common, where O'Connor was called aside and warned 
 by the commissioner of police that the procession must 
 not cross Westminster Bridge. Returning to the car, 
 the perplexed leader harangued the expectant crowd of 
 some 30,000 persons, who represented the militant demo- 
 cracy of the metropolis. He informed them that he had 
 spent six sleepless nights, that his breast was like a coal 
 of fire, that his land scheme would shower countless 
 blessings on them, and that he could not spare one man 
 from the feast. He therefore besought them not to 
 force a way over Westminster Bridge, but to allow their 
 executive committee alone to accompany the petition to 
 Parliament, where he would die upon the floor of the 
 House, or get them their rights. The surprised crowd, 
 which had expected to be led by its champion to death 
 or glory, was cajoled into good-humour by these assur- 
 ances; and few attempted to force a passage across the 
 bridge against the truncheons of the constables. The 
 triumphal cars also remained on the unprivileged shore 
 of the river, and the giant petition itself was carried in
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 141 
 
 a cab to St. Stephens, where it was greeted with shouts 
 of derisive laughter. Thus did the Chartist "Mountain" 
 bring forth its mouse. 
 
 The ridicule aroused by the tame result of so much 
 braggadocio was increased when it was found that the 
 giant petition contained not 5,000,000, but less than 
 2,000,000 signatures, many of which were palpable 
 forgeries, such as Flatnose, Punch, Colonel Sibthorpe, 
 Prince Albert, and Victoria Rex. Failure and ridicule 
 produced the usual crop of recriminations among the 
 Chartist leaders, the more determined men, such as 
 Harney and Ernest Jones, bitterly inveighing against 
 the cowardice of O'Connor. Amidst these disputes the 
 National Convention dwindled away; and the relics of 
 physical-force Chartism were dispersed after two or three 
 vain attempts at sedition in the summer months, attempts 
 which had the sole effect of leading to prison those who 
 had taken too seriously the bluster of the physical-force 
 leaders. 
 
 But for the extraordinary successes of French, Italian, 
 and German democrats in the spring it is questionable 
 whether physical-force Chartism would ever have raised 
 its head in 1848. It was a rather artificial imitation of 
 the recent demonstrations of continental democrats, 
 which had terrorized the governments at Naples, Paris, 
 Berlin, and Vienna. The events of the time served to 
 reveal to the world the stability of British institutions 
 as contrasted with the inherent weakness of continental 
 despotisms. The lesson was well learnt by Englishmen ; 
 and ultimately it was to bear fruit across the Channel. 
 
 Such was the end of the revolutionary stage of English 
 Radicalism. The imprisonment of its more zealous 
 advocates at London and in Lancashire, and the pitiful 
 squabbles of its remaining leaders soon divested the 
 movement of all practical importance. Instead of fol- 
 lowing the course of its decline, we may more profitably
 
 143 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 notice the relation of the movement to latter-day Radi- 
 calism. That veteran champion of financial reform, Mr. 
 Hume, in May, 1849, started a movement for obtaining 
 further remissions of taxation for the working-classes; 1 
 and even O'Connor gave his support to men whom he 
 had previously denounced as selfish bourgeois. 
 
 But Hume was not the first to agitate for a stringently 
 democratic reform in our taxation. He was anticipated 
 by William Lovett, who added to his past services to 
 the working-classes by founding a People's League on 
 the ruins of physical-force Chartism. Seeing that the 
 agitation for a drastic electoral reform had fallen into 
 disrepute, Lovett urged the need of further changes in 
 taxation. Peel's income-tax had already placed finan- 
 cial burdens on the broadest and strongest backs. Lovett 
 proposed entirely to free weak backs from those burdens, 
 which were to fall exclusively on the wealthy. In the 
 forefront of its programme the People's League demanded 
 the complete repeal of all taxes imposed on food and on 
 the materials or processes of industry. In a word, it 
 proposed the complete abolition of all indirect taxation, 
 and the substitution of a direct tax on property, gradu- 
 ated according to the wealth of the possessor. This, as 
 far as I have been able to find, is the first appearance of 
 this demand as a "plank" in the democratic platform. 
 The claim, it is true, had previously been urged by 
 Mazzini in his Young Europe Association, and had found 
 a place among the speculations of that inflexible disciple 
 of Robespierre, the fanatical young St. Just. But Lovett 
 was the first to embody it in an English political pro- 
 gramme. This is not the place to discuss either its 
 
 1 On June 31, 1848, Hume also brought forward a motion for household 
 suffrage, the ballot, triennial Parliaments, and the approximate equalization 
 of electoral areas to population. He stated that five out of every six adult 
 males were without votes. The motion was defeated by 351 to 84. 
 
 In 1851 Mr. Locke King's motion, the first of the kind, for the assimilation 
 t>f the borough and county franchise, was defeated by 299 to 83.
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 143 
 
 justice or its feasibility. Derived by Mazzini from the 
 reds of the first French Republic, it remained a mere 
 opinion, until the success of Peel's experiments in 
 1842-1848 seems to have impelled Lovett to give it the 
 first place in the new Radical creed, where it still holds 
 a prominent place. 
 
 Another link connecting 1 Chartism with more recent 
 developments was the endeavour of O'Connor and some 
 associates to bring- about a union of various democratic 
 clubs in the National Charter and Social Reform Union. 
 The title is significant. It seemed to admit that the 
 Charter alone could scarcely lead democrats to victory. 
 The schism caused by the fiasco of April 10, 1848, was 
 too deep to be healed, unless new sources of enthusiasm 
 diverted attention from the personal disputes of the past. 
 O'Connor had always had a leaning towards social ex- 
 periments, and he now proposed that the new union 
 should undertake to support the co-operative movements 
 and similar efforts for the improvement of artisan life. 
 Had he not been naturally suspected by many genuine 
 co-operators, possibly the new industrial movement might 
 have marched hand in hand with reviving Chartism. It 
 was not to be. The distrust felt in O'Connor was now 
 redoubled, owing to the failure of his Land Company in 
 a way which exposed him to merciless charges of dis- 
 honesty from his former colleagues, Ernest Jones and 
 Harney. This last blow was fatal alike to his waning 
 reputation and to his tottering reason. The closing 
 scenes of the great agitator's life were not devoid of 
 pathos, as when the cottiers on the Land Company's 
 estate at O'Connorville presented him an address of 
 sympathy and thanks for his agrarian efforts ; or when, 
 at the greeting accorded to Kossuth, the great Hungarian 
 patriot, in 1851, the still stalwart Irishman ran up to the 
 illustrious visitor on the platform and wrung his hand 
 with maudlin effusiveness. Failing in his Land Company,
 
 144 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 losing control over his Northern Star, and bankrupt in 
 reputation, O'Connor sank to rest in a private lunatic 
 asylum. The fleeting nature of the popularity which he 
 had striven to gain and to hold was revealed by two 
 suggestive facts. A national subscription commenced 
 by the men of Nottingham realized only ^32 for the man 
 who, during the first eleven years of the reign, had been 
 the idol of the populace ; and that once formidable paper, 
 the Northern Star, after being bought by its former 
 printers for ,100, forthwith advised Radicals to abandon 
 the terms Charter and Chartist as " offensive both to 
 sight and taste ", and to concentrate their efforts on 
 gaining universal suffrage and the ballot. 
 
 The general despair felt by Chartists (except by such 
 stalwarts as Ernest Jones and Harney), and the collapse 
 of O'Connor's social programme, left the ground free for 
 a far healthier influence, that of Maurice, Kingsley, and 
 the school of Christian socialists. Amidst the excitements 
 of the spring of 1848, and the disappointments which 
 ensued, these two earnest leaders, by voice and pen, had 
 striven to point the way to self-help as a safer, if less 
 exciting, road than that of blustering demonstrations; 
 and their manly counsels, reinforced by those of "Tom 
 Hughes", soon strengthened the hold which co-operation 
 was gaining over the artisans of the Midlands and the 
 North. There was indeed every need to encourage and 
 guide the great co-operative movement, so that it might 
 realize the highest aims of its founders, who looked not 
 to thrift alone, but also to the cultivation of the social 
 virtues, and to the training of that corporate spirit in 
 which the British workmen were so lamentably deficient. 
 No thinking man could study the events of 1840-1850 
 without seeing that the failure of Chartism was due to 
 the obstinate egotism both of leaders and of the rank 
 and file. Quot homines tot sententice may be written as 
 the motto of the movement, especially after each of the
 
 Revolution or Evolution? 145 
 
 rebuffs which the agitators encountered. How necessary, 
 then, for artisans to learn on a smaller scale, and in their 
 own community, the need of that "give and take", of 
 that self-restraint and patience in adversity, which lubri- 
 cates human society, and renders steady progress possible. 
 Such was, surely, the chief practical lesson interwoven 
 by Kingsley with the plot of his Chartist novel, Alton 
 Locke. That there might be no mistake as to his mean- 
 ing, he pointed his moral by reminding his readers in the 
 preface to the second edition that democracy meant, not 
 the rule of mere numbers, but of a people organized in 
 demoi, in communities ; that is, of a people vitally related 
 by community of spirit. The rule of mere numbers, he 
 asserted, would result in that worst of all tyrannies, an 
 ochlocracy, or mob-rule. His warnings, together with 
 those of Maurice and Tom Hughes, derived additional 
 force from their well-known sympathy with many of the 
 Chartist aims, a sympathy which found expression in 
 manly words of advice and cheering counsel in meetings, 
 where rage at past failures seemed to portend final de- 
 spairing efforts. Thanks to this noble trio, the desultory 
 efforts of the Chartists were largely absorbed by the 
 trade -union and co-operative movements, which had 
 already begun to ameliorate the workmen's position. 
 In the latter of these, at any rate, they learned something 
 of that corporate spirit, and of "the obedience and self- 
 control which it brings ", together with the lesson, so 
 repugnant to John Bull's individualism, that "only he 
 who can obey is fit to rule ". 
 
 Such is a brief outline of the events determining the 
 course of democracy in England in the closing years of 
 the revolutionary period. The agitations which had 
 burst forth on the Continent in 1789 seemed to be for 
 ever suppressed by the complete failures of French, 
 Italian, German, and Hungarian democrats to rear last- 
 ing political structures in the exciting years 1848-1849. 
 
 (M416) K
 
 146 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 The earlier phases of continental democracy undoubtedly 
 exercised a potent influence on English Radicalism in the 
 days of Home Tooke and Tom Paine, and later on 
 imparted to our reform movement of 1830-1832 the 6lan 
 needful for victory. But since that time the influence of 
 the Continent on British politics has steadily declined. 
 The reason is not far to seek. The democratic move- 
 ments of Italy and Germany, which caused most of the 
 unrest of the Continent in 1830-1849, while aiming 
 secondarily at civic rights, were mainly inspired by a 
 longing for national unity and independence of external 
 control. They therefore had little in common with 
 Chartism, which, as we have seen, derived its strength 
 from distress due to economic causes. English demo- 
 cracy has necessarily been both insular and practical, 
 because it has been overshadowed by the sudden growth 
 of economic problems, unparalleled in the history of the 
 world. These problems were being in part solved by 
 factory legislation and fiscal changes at the very time 
 when national claims produced the political explosions 
 of 1848 on the Continent. The imitation by Chartists of 
 continental revolutionary methods was therefore utterly 
 futile, arraying against them here that force of public 
 opinion which at Rome, Milan, Paris, Berlin, and Vienna 
 had enthusiastically greeted the dawn of democracy. 
 The verdict of posterity, however, will probably award 
 to Feargus O'Connor and his associates some scanty meed 
 of praise for unintentionally revealing the strength of 
 British institutions, when despotism and unbridled demo- 
 cracy reduced the Continent to a weltering chaos.
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 147 
 
 Chapter X. 
 Phases of Political Thought. 
 
 As the biting- winds of spring often render good ser- 
 vice by checking a premature growth of vegetation, so 
 the sharp reaction which in and after 1849 blighted the 
 ardent hopes of democrats, was to be ultimately fruitful 
 in good. Alike in the United Kingdom and on the 
 Continent, important divisions in aim and method, 
 which were not realized amidst the enthusiasm of the 
 attack, were made patent by the failure to snatch victory 
 by a coup de main. The disheartened hosts, falling back 
 in confusion, revised their methods, discarded untrust- 
 worthy leaders, strove to quicken the popular intelligence, 
 and sought, when possible, the alliance of monarchs 
 or statesmen who sympathized with the aspirations of 
 their peoples. The Cannae of 1848 evidently called for 
 a Fabian policy of prudence and delay. It was to be 
 rewarded by signal good fortune, the peoples of Italy 
 and Germany finding in each case their patriotic king 
 and statesman ; while in England the cloak of Sir 
 Robert Peel was to fall on an equally gifted successor. 
 These are the chief facts in modern democratic develop- 
 ments, tending not only to assuage revolutionary passion, 
 but to invigorate and solidify the monarchical principle. 
 
 In our own land, the swing of the pendulum, first 
 towards extreme democracy, and then back towards old 
 methods of government, was not so violent as on the 
 Continent, doubtless owing to the long practice of a 
 great part of our people in representative government, 
 and the sense of responsibility and moderation which it 
 develops. Nevertheless, English politics felt not only 
 the influence of the events of 1848, but also of the re- 
 actionary period which followed. Indeed, in 1850-1866,
 
 148 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 British democracy relapsed into a condition almost of 
 torpor when contrasted with the phenomenal activity of 
 the two preceding decades. So remarkable was the 
 change that a well-known Liberal statesman exclaimed 
 in 1858: "The time is coming when we shall have to 
 advertise for a grievance". The saying betrayed little 
 foresight; but it illustrates the complacent optimism of 
 a period dominated by the personality of Palmerston. 
 How different had been the condition of our life and 
 thought twenty years previously, when the prevalence of 
 discontent drew from that typical Tory of the old school, 
 Lord Eldon, the unparliamentary asseveration, that, if 
 he had to begin life over again, he would begin as an 
 agitator! By contrasting the two statements, we may 
 measure the enormous influence of the work of social 
 and financial reform carried out in the interval. 
 
 There were many influences tending to pacify the 
 working-classes of Great Britain besides the collapse of 
 revolutionary efforts in 1848. The gold discoveries of 
 1849-1851 in California and Australia gave an enormous 
 impetus to industry and commerce. The iron horse and 
 the steamship, working in harmonious combination, 
 were opening up all parts of the world to emigration 
 with a cheapness and facility never dreamt of in 1837 ; 
 and every ship-load of emigrants leaving our shores 
 helped to relieve the pressure of population on congested 
 districts, and to prepare the way for an economic solu- 
 tion of the "condition-of-England question". It is true 
 that the many Chartists, and still more the thousands of 
 Irish malcontents, who sought homes beyond the seas, 
 embittered our relations with our colonies, and still more 
 with the United States. But the discontent at any rate 
 passed from the sphere of domestic politics to that of 
 imperial and foreign policy. 
 
 Besides this cause of relief to our overwrought social 
 system, there were the distractions caused by a remark-
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 149 
 
 able series of wars and commotions, from the Crimean 
 War and Indian Mutiny to the great national struggles 
 of Italy and Germany in 1859-1866, and the complica- 
 tions resulting" from the American Civil War. Inter 
 arma silent leges, says the Roman proverb. It holds 
 good in modern times in more ways than one. A 
 practical people like the English thinks but of one thing 
 at a time ; and when public attention was riveted on the 
 events at Sevastopol or Lucknow, on the tremendous 
 struggles of North and South, or on the future destinies 
 of Italy, Prussia, and Austria, little energy was left for 
 questions of parliamentary reform. The one command- 
 ing personality in the English politics of that age was 
 also adverse to any change in the electorate. Lord Pal- 
 merston used his powers of racy speech and dogged will 
 to discourage all motions for reform, and diverted public 
 attention as far as possible to foreign or imperial affairs 
 and to questions of national defence. From the time of 
 his famous "Civis Romanus sum" speech in 1850 to his 
 decease in 1865, foreign politics accordingly held in 
 popular esteem the position claimed in preceding years 
 by domestic questions. The alternation of these two 
 phases of political life has been one of the characteristics 
 of British development, and will probably recur no less 
 decisively in the future. Whenever the United King- 
 dom has fallen into a state of malaise, the electorate has 
 insisted on the postponement of all save the most press- 
 ing considerations of colonial and foreign policy. But 
 when the mitigation of social evils or political discontent 
 has reinvigorated the life-blood of the empire's heart, a 
 dilatation or expansion of effort towards the extremities 
 becomes natural and inevitable. After the exhausting 
 efforts which culminated at Waterloo, a long period of 
 torpor in imperial affairs inevitably supervened, until the 
 recuperative process, wisely directed by Lord Grey and 
 Sir Robert Peel, enabled the mother of nations to send
 
 150 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 forth her swarms of emigrants to occupy the lands which 
 the prowess of her warriors or the genius of her engineers 
 had opened up. The marvellous growth of our colonies 
 in the new era of commercial expansion awakened both 
 our own national pride and the jealousies of our rivals, 
 and thus tended to discredit the views of the "Man- 
 chester School", which regarded colonies as a burden, 
 and foreign policy as a delusion and a snare. In truth, 
 however, both the Cobdens and the Palmerstons exert 
 a useful influence on a people which seeks to combine 
 vigour and liberty at home with political and commercial 
 influence abroad. Without her Cobdens, Peels, and 
 Gladstones, Great Britain might possibly have degener- 
 ated into a second Carthage. Without her Pitts, Pal- 
 merstons, and Beaconsfields, she might have fallen to 
 the level of the Dutch Netherlands. 
 
 Such have been the chief material causes affecting 
 the ebb and flow of English political life. But a wider 
 question here meets us. Is there any connection be- 
 tween the peaceful expansion of the English-speaking 
 peoples and the political thought of the middle of this 
 century? It may be of interest to notice certain influ- 
 ences which the expansion of England has exerted on 
 contemporary thought both in our own and in other 
 countries. The marvellous growth of the English- 
 speaking peoples has been so prominent a feature of 
 modern life, that it could hardly be overlooked either by 
 the politicians or thinkers on the Continent. I shall try 
 to show that the steady growth of British institutions 
 has helped to divert the attention of political thinkers 
 from abstract speculation to patent facts, from the draw- 
 ing up of paper constitutions to a study of the develop- 
 ment of British institutions and of their famous offshoots 
 in the New World. 
 
 A century had elapsed since Montesquieu had extolled 
 our system of balance of political powers as combining
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 151 
 
 the peculiar excellences of monarchy, aristocracy, and 
 democracy in a compromise which possessed the 
 elements of stability. This balance of powers in our 
 constitution was, it is true, vanishing- under the en- 
 croachments of the people's House on the prerogatives 
 of the Crown and the House of Lords. But, it might 
 be argued, these changes in our political customs and 
 procedure were, after all, only the legal recognition of 
 changes which had occurred, and were still occurring, in 
 the life of the people. They served to register the stages 
 of transition from the monarchical and feudal times to 
 the present industrial age, which endows the many with 
 an overwhelming importance. The Act of 1832 and 
 subsequent legislation, when viewed in relation to the 
 momentous developments of the nation's life, proved 
 that the English constitution was, what it had always 
 been, an organic growth vitally related to the body 
 politic, and therefore necessarily expanding in the direc- 
 tion indicated by the most vigorous growth. 
 
 But besides possessing this feature of interest, our 
 institutions claimed the study of political thinkers on yet 
 wider grounds. The development of the English race 
 beyond the seas was to demonstrate the marvellous 
 adaptability of our methods of government to widely 
 diverse conditions. Whatever may be urged as to the 
 many differences between the constitution of the United 
 States and that of the mother country, there can be little 
 doubt as to the British origin of most of the provisions 
 of that famous federal compact. It was this democratic 
 offshoot of British constitutional life, applied to a number 
 of self-governing communities, which engaged the ear- 
 nest attention of that brilliant French thinker, de Tocque- 
 ville. His great work, Democracy in America (1835), 
 was destined, as we shall presently see, to exert a 
 salutary influence on political thought in Europe ; and 
 on no leader of public opinion was the impress of his
 
 152 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 vigorous mind stamped more clearly than on John Stuart 
 Mill, who justly calls him the Montesquieu of the age. 
 In truth, de Tocqueville's great work tended to recall 
 political thought from the sphere of abstract speculation, 
 in which it had aimlessly careered since the advent of 
 Rousseau, to a careful use of the comparative method 
 in which the earlier French thinker had excelled. Ob- 
 servation, comparison, and analysis of existing institu- 
 tions have tended since de Tocqueville's day to resume 
 their rightful ascendency in political thought. 
 
 Another testimony to the vitality of the English con- 
 stitution was seen in its adaptation to the needs of the 
 two discordant provinces of Canada. After the revolts 
 of 1837 a careful inquiry was made into the conditions 
 of political life in Upper and Lower Canada. As a 
 result, the Canada Act of 1840 granted full constitutional 
 rights to these provinces, which were thenceforth united 
 for all save local requirements, the governor appointed 
 by the Crown continuing to discharge all, and more than 
 all, the functions wielded by the sovereign at home. 
 The almost complete success of this experiment afforded 
 indisputable proof of the surprising pliability of our 
 institutions, and tended still further to give a practical 
 turn to the political thought of the age. 
 
 Not only practical men like the Piedmontese states- 
 man Cavour, but the foremost political thinkers of 
 Europe, were now convinced that if representative 
 government was to be securely gained by continental 
 peoples, it must be of a character somewhat akin to that 
 of England. In brief, the democratic ideals of Rousseau 
 or of Bentham gave place to those of de Tocqueville and 
 John Stuart Mill. 
 
 Even before the failure of revolutionary methods in 
 1848-49, there had been noticeable a certain hesitation 
 in the utterances even of ardent reformers. Was demo- 
 cracy the true solution of all difficulties besetting the
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 153 
 
 political relations of mankind? Was it the summum 
 bonum of all public effort? And if so, were the people 
 endowed with the qualities necessary to its successful 
 working-? Such doubts had scarcely ever troubled the 
 minds of its first champions. They are the common- 
 places of all works written since 1830 by open-minded 
 observers, except those of the lone-brooding- seer, Maz- 
 zini, and of the diminishing- band of disciples who were 
 still entranced by the vision of Young- Italy and Young 
 Europe. The Mazzinians remained as almost the sole 
 witnesses to the unquestioning- faith of the earlier gener- 
 ation, when Rousseau assumed as an indisputable fact 
 the equality of man and the supremacy and infallibility 
 of the general will. 
 
 The contrast between the earlier age and the middle 
 and latter part of this century is so marked, that a few 
 suggestions seem to be called for as to the trend of 
 thought from the days of Rousseau, the unconscious 
 precursor of revolutionary thought, down to the time 
 of Mill and Darwin. Nothing can be more absolute 
 than the dogmatism with which Rousseau builds up his 
 ideal democratic system. The people, having agreed 
 by a solemn social compact to form a community for 
 purposes of mutual defence, support, and advancement, 
 forthwith create a state, wherein the general will, as 
 declared directly by the people itself, without the inter- 
 vention of representatives, is paramount. Such a com- 
 munity or state having been formed by the writer with 
 idyllic ease, Rousseau next deduces the attributes of the 
 general will. Arguing with fallacious facility from adjec- 
 tive to adjective, he proves that as the will is general 
 it must also be inalienable, indivisible, incorruptible, 
 unrepresentable, and indestructible. 1 Such an argument 
 would of itself inspire distrust in the present age of dis- 
 
 1 Rousseau, Le Contrat Social (1774), bk. ii. An English edition has 
 recently been edited by Mr. Tozer, with introduction.
 
 154 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 illusionment ; but the literary skill of the writer and the 
 symmetry of his completed system constituted at once 
 the charm and the danger of the new political evangel 
 to the men of 1789 in France, and even to the more 
 practical Home Tookes and Tom Paines on this side 
 of the Channel. And all this, it should be observed, 
 was derived by verbal legerdemain from the first postu- 
 late of Rousseau's political geometry, the assumed social 
 contract, from which our own thinker, Hobbes, had de- 
 duced the justice and necessity of an absolute monarchy. 
 What wonder that Burke called Rousseau's book, and 
 the resulting declaration of the rights of man of 1789, 
 "chaff and rags and paltry blurred sheets of paper 
 about the rights of man"! A dreary, bloody interval 
 was, however, to elapse before thinkers ceased to delude 
 mankind by their logical Utopias, and, returning to 
 solid fact, recognized that politics was an experimental 
 science. 
 
 The conviction of the absolute truth of the democratic 
 creed and of its superiority to all other theories of 
 government was asserted with undiminished fervour by 
 another great political thinker of that age, Jeremy Ben- 
 tham. Approaching his subject by methods of inquiry, 
 based on a careful analysis of forms of government and 
 of the motives of human action, the Englishman never- 
 theless arrived at conclusions well-nigh as sweeping as 
 those of Rousseau. 1 Scorning the system of checks 
 and balances which endeared the British constitution 
 to Montesquieu, Bentham advocated an unbridled demo- 
 cracy. The monarchy and the House of Lords were 
 therefore to vanish, yielding their powers to a House 
 of Commons elected by universal suffrage, which was 
 to enforce absolutely the will of the majority not only 
 in legislation but by the most complete and exacting 
 control over the executive departments of government. 
 1 See cb. ii. of this work.
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 155 
 
 "He exhausted" (says John Stuart Mill 1 ) "all the 
 resources of ingenuity in devising- means for riveting 
 the yoke of public opinion closer and closer round the 
 necks of all public functionaries, and excluding- every 
 possibility of the slightest or most temporary influence 
 either by a minority or by the functionary's own notions 
 of right." To such a length did Bentham's enthusiasm 
 for utility carry him in the very natural disgust at the 
 sordid Whig oligarchy of the times of Walpole and the 
 Pelhams and the monarchical state-craft of George III. 
 The arbitrariness of the new democratic government is 
 not the only noticeable feature in Bentham's scheme. 
 Equally remarkable is the baldness and rigidity of its 
 presentment. The utilitarian philosopher urged his 
 claims with complete disregard of historical associations 
 and human sentiment. Great, indeed, must have been 
 the potential vigour of his leading ideas to have made 
 many converts, when set forth in a garb so unattractive 
 and even repellent. "Victorious analysis" menaced 
 mankind with a form of democracy which would have 
 merited Burke's crushing criticism, a "multiplied ty- 
 ranny". We seem to picture Bentham's triumphant 
 democracy as reducing the world to a state resembling 
 that described by astronomers, when our planet was a 
 cheerless expanse of waters sweeping in tidal waves that 
 were checked and diverted by no friendly continents. 
 Such would be the flux and reflux of Bentham's all- 
 dominating democratic opinion. 
 
 The experience of the successive spasms of revolution 
 in 1789-1799, the return to a military despotism under 
 the great Napoleon, and the failure of the French Re- 
 volution of 1830, discredited the rigid systems of Rous- 
 seau and Bentham. Talleyrand's mot on taking the 
 oath to the constitution of 1830 " It is the thirteenth" 
 may serve as epitaph to the earlier generation of 
 
 1 J. S. Mill, Essay on Bentham,
 
 156 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 constitution builders. In their place came leaders of a 
 more practical turn of mind, inspired with a distrust of 
 constitutions based on abstract reasoning, and with a 
 deepening desire to seek some foundation in fact, some 
 compromise with the actual. 
 
 The failure of the philosophic constitution builders on 
 the Continent of Europe, and the success attending the 
 development of British methods of government, are the 
 dominant facts in the history of modern politics. Their 
 results on political thought have been considerable. 
 Thenceforth nearly all inquirers into political science 
 have been content to abandon all efforts to deduce 
 results from first principles. They have generally sat- 
 isfied themselves with a humbler but assuredly safer 
 method, namely, the collection of facts relating to man's 
 life and conduct as an individual and in a community, 
 and have striven by a comparison of these data to arrive 
 at conclusions which may be regarded provisionally 
 as working hypotheses. The reason for this change 
 of attitude is obvious. The schools of Rousseau and 
 Bentham had not understood the full complexity of 
 the problem which they attempted to solve. They un- 
 derstood neither man as an individual nor human 
 society. Their data being imperfect, their conclusions 
 were bound to be faulty and one-sided. The work of 
 their successors has therefore been to make good the 
 gaps, to study man and society in the light of the investi- 
 gations of natural science, and to endeavour to correlate 
 the immense mass of facts brought to light by the biolo- 
 gist, the economist, and the scientific school of historians. 
 We are still in the midst of this phase ; and it therefore 
 behoves students of political science still to adhere to 
 the comparative and inductive methods of de Tocque- 
 ville. 
 
 Space will not permit of any notice of de Tocque- 
 ville's work. Its chief importance for us here is that it
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 157 
 
 exercised a great influence on one of the keenest of 
 English political thinkers, John Stuart Mill. Reared by 
 his father, James Mill, in an atmosphere saturated with 
 exact knowledge, he learnt from de Tocqueville the 
 limits to the operation of logic on man's social and 
 political relations. He ceased to be a mere Benthamite, 
 a "mere reasoning machine". 1 He no longer regarded 
 happiness as the sole aim of human society, utility as 
 the only test of legislation, or the rule of the majority as 
 the sine qua non of civic life. De Tocqueville's book 
 proved to his keen and receptive mind the superiority of 
 the historical and comparative method in politics over 
 that of argument from first principles. It taught him 
 how to trace back both the excellences and defects of 
 American life to democratic institutions. Democracy 
 thenceforth ceased to be to him the absolute and un- 
 questionable truth of man's public life. He now regarded 
 it as a method of government, desirable on the whole, 
 liable to grave abuse in some respects, and clearly open 
 to many improvements. 
 
 Perhaps the contrast between the earlier and later 
 phases of democratic thought will be best realized if we 
 place side by side some characteristic utterances of the 
 earlier and later phases of John Stuart Mill's career. 
 The first passage represents the rigid methods of his 
 father James Mill, a firm Benthamite, who regarded 
 politics as a purely deductive science analogous to 
 geometry. Its postulates and axioms being granted, 
 the science of politics could be constructed as symmetri- 
 cally as that of geometry, and could be proved to lead 
 to the adoption of the will of the majority. The most 
 perfect political system, accordingly, was that which 
 would infallibly ensure this result. A convinced Ben- 
 thamite like James Mill entertained as little doubt about 
 the practical side of government as he did concerning 
 
 1 J. S. Mill's Autobiography, ch. 4 [p. 109, ist edit.]
 
 158 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 its principles. John Stuart Mill in his Autobiography 
 states that his father had ' ' an almost unbounded con- 
 fidence in the efficacy of two things: representative 
 government, and complete freedom of discussion. . . He 
 felt as if all would be gained if the whole population 
 were taught to read, if all sorts of opinions were allowed 
 to be addressed to them in word and in writing, and if 
 by means of the suffrage they could nominate a legisla- 
 ture to give effect to the opinions they adopted. He 
 thought that when the legislature no longer represented 
 a class interest it would aim at the general interest, 
 honestly and with adequate wisdom; since the people 
 would be sufficiently under the guidance of educated in- 
 telligence to make in general a good choice of persons 
 to represent them ; and having done so, to leave to those 
 whom they chose a liberal discretion." 
 
 Various circumstances concurred to shake the son's 
 faith in his father's creed. Macaulay's keen criticism 
 of James Mill's Essay on Government convinced John 
 Stuart Mill that his father's system was founded on too 
 narrow a basis, since it ignored several essential factors. 
 With his usual openness of mind, he revised his views 
 on politics, no longer looking on representative demo- 
 cracy as an "essential principle", but "as a question of 
 time, place, and circumstance"; and though he still 
 cherished his former political belief, he thenceforth re- 
 garded "the choice of political institutions as a moral 
 and educational question", &c. The very moderate 
 success which the Reform Bill of 1832 attained was 
 another disappointment; but more important was the 
 impression produced on the young thinker by de Tocque- 
 ville's Democracy in America, which led to a shifting of 
 his political ideal from pure democracy to that modified 
 form of it set forth in his later works. 1 
 
 The reasons for this toning down of his democratic 
 
 1 Autobiography, p. 191, ist edit.
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 159 
 
 ardour are set forth in many of his writings after 1835; 
 but perhaps in none so clearly and emphatically as in 
 his Essay on Bentham (1838). After awarding" due praise 
 to his early master, he points out the chief practical 
 defect in his political science. Bentham neglected to 
 assign proper importance to differences of national 
 character as determined by past history and habits of 
 thought. But, besides this very obvious criticism, Mill 
 urges one which is fundamental. He boldly challenges 
 Bentham's assertion that the will of the majority must 
 under all conditions be paramount : " Is it, at all 
 times and places, good for mankind to be under the 
 absolute authority of the majority of themselves? . . . 
 Is it the proper condition of man in all ages and nations, 
 to be under the despotism of Public Opinion?" Here 
 we notice a mental attitude totally distinct from the 
 unswerving faith of Mill's early years. The principle of 
 ' 'the greatest happiness of the greatest number" is 
 also attacked, partly because, as Mill elsewhere says, 
 happiness is too complex a state of mind and body to 
 serve as a satisfactory goal of human strivings; but 
 chiefly because the rule of the majority alone will not 
 necessarily lead to the best obtainable results. He 
 frankly admits that an absolute democracy might tend 
 not to level up mankind, but to level it down. He points 
 out that the majority of mankind must always be un- 
 skilled manual labourers, and that the rule of such a 
 majority might tend "to make one narrow mean type 
 of human nature universal and perpetual, and to crush 
 every influence which tends to the further improvement 
 of man's intellectual and moral nature. There must, we 
 know, be some paramount power in society; and that 
 the majority should be that power, is on the whole right, 
 not as being just in itself, but as being less unjust than 
 any other footing on which the matter can be placed. 
 But it is necessary that the institutions of society should
 
 160 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 make provision for keeping up, in some form or other, 
 as a corrective to partial views, and a shelter for freedom 
 of thought and individuality of character, a perpetual 
 and standing Opposition to the will of the majority. . . 
 A centre of resistance round which all the moral and 
 social elements which the ruling power views with dis- 
 favour may cluster, and behind whose bulwarks they 
 may find shelter from the attempts of that power to hunt 
 them out of existence, is as necessary where the opinion 
 of the majority is sovereign, as where the ruling power 
 is a hierarchy or an aristocracy. Where no such point 
 d'appui exists, there the human race will inevitably de- 
 generate; and the question whether the United States, 
 for instance, will in time sink into another China (also a 
 most commercial and industrious nation) resolves itself, 
 to us, into the question whether such a centre of resist- 
 ance will gradually evolve itself, or not." 
 
 In this remarkable pronouncement the reaction from 
 Bentham to de Tocqueville is everywhere conspicuous. 
 The age of faith has vanished: that of criticism has 
 dawned. If such was the case with so utilitarian a 
 Radical as John Stuart Mill, it is not surprising that 
 after the almost ludicrous collapse of democratic efforts 
 in 1848, unbelievers like Thomas Carlyle should pro- 
 claim that democracy was a self-cancelling process, 
 leading to anarchy "happy if it be anarchy plus a 
 street constable "- 1 As the later political utterances of 
 Carlyle were destined to have little more than rhapsodic 
 interest, we may be pardoned for omitting any reference 
 to them here, especially as their contradiction by the 
 complete - suffrage party has been noticed in chapter 
 VIII. It will be of more practical importance to trace 
 the further development of Mill's views on the subject of 
 safeguarding the rights of the minority under a demo- 
 cratic government. 
 
 1 Carlyle, Latter Day Pamphlets, No. i (1850).
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 161 
 
 These views took definite shape in his work, Con- 
 siderations on Representative Government (1861), wherein 
 his objections to the absolute rule of a majority lead 
 to some practical suggestions. After asserting- that 
 representation in proportion to numbers is the first 
 principle of democracy, he devotes nearly a whole chap- 
 ter to a review of various contrivances for safeguarding 
 the rights of the minority, without which, he asserts, 
 there can be no true democracy. Despite his admira- 
 tion for the political spirit animating the people of the 
 United States, Mill condemns their constitution as " a 
 false democracy, which instead of giving representation 
 to all, gives it only to the local majorities ". 
 
 Mill here cites what is perhaps the extreme case of 
 government by local majorities; for in the election of 
 the Senate the majorities gained in States, which differ 
 vastly in population and importance, determine the com- 
 position of the august body which guards the federal 
 compact. Over against this striking instance of what 
 we may term federalized democracy the great philo- 
 sopher places a system of proportional representation 
 which, he claims, would not only save the minority 
 from temporary political extinction, but would ensure 
 the election of the wisest and best. He accords the 
 highest praise to a work of Mr. Hare on The Election 
 of Representatives (1859) as being "almost a specific" 
 against the evils incidental to local representation. He 
 welcomed Mr. Hare's plan of proportional representation 
 for two reasons : first, as providing a far more accurate 
 gauge of public opinion; and secondly, as being likely 
 to result in the election of more intelligent members of 
 Parliament. Before noticing the general details of Mr. 
 Hare's plan, a word or two may not be out of place 
 respecting the evils which it was devised to cure. The 
 chief defect of the existing system was the predominance 
 at election times of local over national interests. Wire- 
 
 (H416) L
 
 162 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 pullers sought, not for the ablest candidate, but for 
 one who would do well for the town or district. Petty 
 interests therefore usurped the place which ought to be 
 occupied by national concerns; so that members were 
 too often chosen, not for their ability on questions of 
 national and imperial import, but because of their suc- 
 cessful catering- for the interests of gas and water com- 
 panies, or their liberal donations to the local infirmary. 
 
 It must be confessed that there is great force in this 
 objection. The result is seen in the strength of what 
 may be called the parochial spirit in a Parliament which 
 controls the destinies of a world-wide empire. Even so 
 complacent a Whig as Mr. Bagehot admitted the "opu- 
 lent profusion of dulness" in the Parliament of Lord 
 Palmerston's day; and it may not unfairly be attributed 
 to the bewilderment of the parochial intellect when sud- 
 denly confronted with complex international questions. 
 With a characteristic blending of acuteness and irony, 
 of large-hearted hope and almost cynical scepticism, 
 Mill noted that "the tendency of representative govern- 
 ment, as of modern civilization, is towards collective 
 mediocrity, and this tendency is increased by all reduc- 
 tions and extensions of the franchise ". How much 
 more necessary, then, that this defect of a democratic 
 age should not be exaggerated by a faulty system 
 of parliamentary election, but should to some extent 
 be cured by the legislation of the wisest and best. 1 
 Such a result would be secured, so Hare and Mill con- 
 tended, by substituting national for local election. 
 According to this plan, the whole body of electors 
 would be divided by the number of members to be 
 returned at that time 658; and the resulting quotient 
 would determine the number of votes needed for actual 
 election of any one member to Parliament, though the 
 
 1 Compare Mazzini's definition of democracy, "The progress of all, 
 through all, under the lead of the wisest and best ".
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 163 
 
 votes so given would be wholly irrespective of locality. 
 A voter would, on this plan, be able to record his vote 
 for any candidate in any part of the kingdom. His vote 
 would only be counted for one candidate ; but he could 
 add other names, in order of preference, and if the 
 object of his first choice was not successful through not 
 obtaining the requisite number of votes, still his vote 
 would not be thrown away, but would probably aid the 
 return of some member. To prevent very popular can- 
 didates from engrossing nearly all the votes, any one of 
 them was to be credited only with so many as were 
 requisite to secure his return; the remainder of those 
 who voted for him would have their votes counted for 
 the next candidates on their respective lists. 
 
 Without entering into further details of this interesting 
 proposal, it is evidently open to very grave objections 
 on the score of its complexity, at least for an unintel- 
 ligent electorate; besides which the great clerical labour 
 involved would expose it to risks of inaccuracy where 
 so vast a number of votes had to be assessed. It is 
 true, as is claimed by Mr. Hare in the Appendices to 
 his third edition, that the elections to the Danish 
 Rigsrad, or Supreme Legislative Council, had been since 
 1855 conducted on a somewhat similar system, and 
 apparently with success. But it is hazardous to argue 
 from the case of a small kingdom with an homogeneous 
 population to a society so varied in race, interests, and 
 intelligence as that of the United Kingdom. It may 
 be granted, however, that proportionate representation 
 is the ideal towards which democracy should strive. 
 The method is logically perfect, it imposes on voters 
 the need of an intelligent survey of national questions 
 and of the record of other than local politicians, and 
 above all it frees the election of the nation's represen- 
 tatives from those petty parochial concerns which at 
 present warp and complicate the main issues.
 
 164 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 I propose to notice only a few other of the suggestions 
 contained in Mill's Representative Government, namely 
 those which have an intimate relation with practical 
 politics, and which serve to connect the thought of his 
 day with the Reform Bills of 1860-1867. In his chapter 
 on the extension of the suffrage he again expresses his 
 distrust of a form of democracy determined solely by 
 local elections a "false democracy" he calls it, in 
 which the minority would have no appropriate influence. 
 He cherished a deep-rooted apprehension that the rule 
 of the many would be a vulgar and sordid tyranny fatal 
 to intelligence and all forms of individual excellence, 
 and the utmost he would concede was that he would 
 " not despair of the operation even of equal and 
 universal suffrage, if made real by the proportional 
 representation of all minorities, on Mr. Hare's prin- 
 ciple". But even when this ideal plan of voting is 
 postulated, Mill also claims that there shall be some 
 other safeguards to intelligence and wealth against the 
 levelling-down tendencies which he associates with the 
 rule of a mere majority. These safeguards are to con- 
 sist in the exclusion from the electorate of all who do 
 not pay taxes to the state, of all paupers, bankrupts, 
 and illiterate persons. He justifies the exclusion of the 
 first two classes on the ground that only those who 
 have some pecuniary interest in the state can curb the 
 lavish expenditure prevalent, for example, in American 
 municipal affairs, and resulting from manhood suffrage. 
 The exclusion of illiterate persons he also claims as 
 necessary to the intelligent conduct of public affairs and 
 a tribute to the superiority of knowledge over ignorance. 
 With this plea, again, it is impossible to avoid sympathy ; 
 and it yet remains to be seen whether the enfranchise- 
 ment of a large number of illiterates is not a danger not 
 only to the stability but even to the liberties of the 
 community; for it is just these who are most open, not
 
 Phases of Political Thought. 165 
 
 only to the arts of the demagogue, but to the bribes of 
 the wealthy and of their parasites. Yet, while granting 
 Mill's main contention, it is difficult to take quite 
 seriously his suggestion that qualification for a vote 
 should be withheld unless the claimant " should, in the 
 presence of the registrar, copy a sentence from an Eng- 
 lish book, and perform a sum in the rule of three ". 
 
 Those who echo John Bright's off-hand criticism of 
 Disraeli's Reform Bill and its "fancy franchises", may 
 be asked to remember that some of these very franchises 
 were proposed by John Stuart Mill himself. In the 
 chapter from which I have quoted, the philosopher 
 claimed the right of plurality of votes, not on the ground 
 of wealth, which he rightly held to be a most undesir- 
 able test of personal capacity, but by virtue of the dis- 
 charge of difficult and responsible duties which demand 
 skill, foresight, and intelligence. Two or three votes 
 apiece should accordingly, he claims, be awarded to 
 every master manufacturer, merchant, banker, or gradu- 
 ate of a university, in fact to everyone who might be 
 expected to be by calling or by education more intelligent 
 than the average man. Wisely refraining from descend- 
 ing to details on these topics, Mill contented himself with 
 enunciating the principle that competence in business or 
 high mental endowments should find adequate recog- 
 nition in the most important of all civic functions, the 
 discharge of electoral duty. To those who gibe at the 
 proposal as academic, it may suffice to reply that the 
 sneer will be justified when democracy of the present 
 type has justified its existence for more than a genera- 
 tion. At present its trial has scarcely commenced. In 
 the history of peoples and institutions, even a century 
 would be scarcely a sufficient space to justify the boast 
 of latter-day prophets, that democracy of the " one man 
 one vote " type is the final stage of human development. 
 
 Quitting the unpractical sphere of prophecy, it will be
 
 166 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 more fitting- to notice another important development in 
 the scientific, and ultimately in the political thought of 
 our age. The most fertile idea of the century assumed 
 definite form when Darwin in 1859 published his famous 
 work, The Origin of Species. It is true that the doctrine 
 of evolution had been foreshadowed by previous writers 
 both in the domains of natural and of social science; 
 but Darwin's statement in successive works ensured for 
 it an immense vogue and a triumphant justification. 
 
 Into the political questions raised by Darwin's theories 
 it is neither possible nor desirable to enter at any length. 
 Their influence has been both to extend and complicate 
 the issues which were prominent in the previous genera- 
 tion. Then controversy raged mostly on the question 
 of natural rights, especially those of the individual to a 
 share in the government. Now the contest is between 
 those who would strengthen and those who would 
 minimize the authority of the state in its dealings with 
 the individual, especially in regard to private ownership, 
 the claims of companies, and economic or social ques- 
 tions arising therefrom. Indeed, owing to the growth 
 of industrialism, and the extended survey over human 
 relations which has resulted from the researches of 
 Darwin and Herbert Spencer, political discussions are 
 no longer limited to the narrow channel of "natural 
 right ", but tend to merge themselves in an illimitable 
 sea of social and economic inquiry. 
 
 One practical result of the theory of evolution may, 
 however, be noted here. On all thinking men, and 
 indirectly through them on the unthinking 1 , it has exer- 
 cised a most important influence in exposing" the folly 
 both of immobility and of sudden and reckless change 
 in the political world. It depicts human life and society 
 as an orderly development, proceeding not by leaps and 
 bounds, still less with long spells of absolute torpor, but 
 on principles of growth determined by the nature of
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 167 
 
 human society and of its environment. The study of 
 man, of his past efforts, even of his failures in politics 
 and social life, is therefore one essential to any intelligent 
 forecast of his future; for the institutions and laws 
 which embody the wisdom of his forefathers are, so 
 to speak, the political environment which moulds his 
 action, arouses his antipathies, or wings his aspirations. 
 A close and reverent study of the past has therefore 
 become more than ever necessary to the politician who 
 would rise above the level of Little Peddlington. Such 
 a study reveals at once the need of adapting old institu- 
 tions to new needs, and the folly of heedlessly stripping 
 off from the body politic customs which have shaped 
 its growth. In brief, Darwinism has extinguished the 
 Toryism of pre-reform days, and has all but banished 
 from our political life the abolitionist mania of the suc- 
 ceeding generation. 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867, 
 
 We have now considered the causes, both in the 
 world of fact and in the sphere of thought, which led 
 to a sifting of the earlier democratic creed, the rejection 
 of its more sweeping demands, and the postponement of 
 any effective agitation on the whole question. The epoch 
 1850-1866 may perhaps best be described by a reference 
 to the terms used by the followers of the French thinker 
 St. Simon. They called certain eras in history organic 
 when a people or a creed expanded by its sheer vitality 
 and force; but when the time of unconscious or inevit- 
 able expansion was succeeded by one of discussion and 
 unrest, they applied to this new age the term critical. 
 Now, this latter epithet may be applied to the years
 
 168 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 1850-1866, in regard to constitutional reform; while, 
 on the whole, the epoch which succeeded, especially the 
 years 1867-1873 and 1880-1885, may be described as 
 organic in relation to democracy. Not that these epithets 
 sum up all the characteristics of the periods to which we 
 apply them ; but they may serve as convenient mental 
 labels, summing up our general impressions as to the 
 flux and reflux of the Euripus of our modern political 
 life, in which the eddies and swirls become ever more 
 perplexing. The most casual glance over our party 
 history will convince the observer that the labels critical 
 and organic, as applied to epochs, are not wholly accu- 
 rate, still less mutually exclusive. In the period 1851- 
 1866 many proposals for electoral reform were brought 
 forward. But then they all failed : and the charac- 
 teristic of an "organic" period is the apparently irresist- 
 ible nature of its expansion. More important is it to 
 notice that, even in this time of sifting of opinions, two 
 noteworthy gains were effected for the proletariate. One 
 facilitated the enlightenment of public opinion : the other 
 opened the doors of the House of Commons to merit 
 irrespective of property. 
 
 The former of these movements, that for the removal 
 of the remaining "taxes on knowledge", may be con- 
 sidered as a natural sequel to the efforts of 1836, and 
 attained a successful issue in 1855 and I86I. 1 The 
 repeal of the paper duty in 1861 was rendered memorable 
 by the last serious struggle which has occurred between 
 the Lords and Commons on a financial question. The 
 government bill of 1860, which proposed the abolition 
 of the paper duty, had passed its third reading in the 
 Commons by the narrow majority of 219 to 210. This 
 apparently emboldened the Lords to reject the measure, 
 
 x For further details on this subject see The Life of John Bright, by C. A. 
 Vince, M.A., in this series. It shows the great influence of John Bright on 
 the political developments of his time.
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 169 
 
 which was in effect, though not in form, a money bill. 
 Technically, no doubt, this vote of the Lords was not a 
 contravention of the constitution ; but, as was privately 
 pointed out by Lord John Russell to his phlegmatic chief, 
 Palmerston, "the exercise of a right which has lain 
 dormant since the Revolution (of 1688) must give a great 
 shock to the constitution ". However much the premier 
 desired to hush up the imminent dispute between the 
 two Houses, he was pushed on, not only by Lord John 
 Russell, but by a far more vehement personality. Mr. 
 Gladstone was the most famous of the group of " Peel- 
 ites" who had recently rallied to the Liberal cause. 
 Devotion to Free-trade principles and to the Italian 
 cause, which the Palmerston cabinet championed, had 
 at last led the former " hope of the Conservative party" 
 into the Whig camp ; and he was now chancellor of the 
 exchequer. The vote of the Lords on a financial ques- 
 tion touched Mr. Gladstone in one of his tenderest points; 
 and he fired off a "magnificently mad speech on the 
 privilege question". 1 For a time it seemed doubtful 
 whether Palmerston would throw down the gauntlet to 
 the Lords or accept Mr. Gladstone's resignation. As 
 Mr. Gladstone was a necessity, the gauntlet was thrown 
 down. Under the plea of maintaining their privileges 
 on money questions, the government passed resolutions 
 safeguarding similar proposals for the future; and by 
 including their financial scheme in one very compre- 
 hensive bill, carried their resolutions as regards the 
 paper duty (1861). This solution of the question is 
 interesting, not only as marking the legal ratification of 
 what had been only a prescriptive right of the Lower 
 House, but also as illustrating the speedy development 
 of democratic principles in Mr. Gladstone's nature. 
 The other question which calls for brief notice is the 
 
 1 The expression was Earl Russell's. Life of Lord John Russell, by S. 
 Walpole, vol. ii. p. 344.
 
 168 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 1850-1866, in regard to constitutional reform; while, 
 on the whole, the epoch which succeeded, especially the 
 years 1867-1873 and 1880-1885, may be described as 
 organic in relation to democracy. Not that these epithets 
 sum up all the characteristics of the periods to which we 
 apply them ; but they may serve as convenient mental 
 labels, summing up our general impressions as to the 
 flux and reflux of the Euripus of our modern political 
 life, in which the eddies and swirls become ever more 
 perplexing. The most casual glance over our party 
 history will convince the observer that the labels critical 
 and organic, as applied to epochs, are not wholly accu- 
 rate, still less mutually exclusive. In the period 1851- 
 1866 many proposals for electoral reform were brought 
 forward. But then they all failed : and the charac- 
 teristic of an "organic" period is the apparently irresist- 
 ible nature of its expansion. More important is it to 
 notice that, even in this time of sifting of opinions, two 
 noteworthy gains were effected for the proletariate. One 
 facilitated the enlightenment of public opinion : the other 
 opened the doors of the House of Commons to merit 
 irrespective of property. 
 
 The former of these movements, that for the removal 
 of the remaining "taxes on knowledge", may be con- 
 sidered as a natural sequel to the efforts of 1836, and 
 attained a successful issue in 1855 and I86:. 1 The 
 repeal of the paper duty in 1861 was rendered memorable 
 by the last serious struggle which has occurred between 
 the Lords and Commons on a financial question. The 
 government bill of 1860, which proposed the abolition 
 of the paper duty, had passed its third reading in the 
 Commons by the narrow majority of 219 to 210. This 
 apparently emboldened the Lords to reject the measure, 
 
 1 For further details on this subject see The Life of John Bright, by C. A. 
 Vince, M.A., in this series. It shows the great influence of John Bright on 
 the political developments of his time.
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 169 
 
 which was in effect, though not in form, a money bill. 
 Technically, no doubt, this vote of the Lords was not a 
 contravention of the constitution ; but, as was privately 
 pointed out by Lord John Russell to his phlegmatic chief, 
 Palmerston, "the exercise of a right which has lain 
 dormant since the Revolution (of 1688) must give a great 
 shock to the constitution ". However much the premier 
 desired to hush up the imminent dispute between the 
 two Houses, he was pushed on, not only by Lord John 
 Russell, but by a far more vehement personality. Mr. 
 Gladstone was the most famous of the group of " Peel- 
 ites" who had recently rallied to the Liberal cause. 
 Devotion to Free-trade principles and to the Italian 
 cause, which the Palmerston cabinet championed, had 
 at last led the former " hope of the Conservative party" 
 into the Whig camp ; and he was now chancellor of the 
 exchequer. The vote of the Lords on a financial ques- 
 tion touched Mr. Gladstone in one of his tenderest points; 
 and he fired off a "magnificently mad speech on the 
 privilege question". 1 For a time it seemed doubtful 
 whether Palmerston would throw down the gauntlet to 
 the Lords or accept Mr. Gladstone's resignation. As 
 Mr. Gladstone was a necessity, the gauntlet was thrown 
 down. Under the plea of maintaining their privileges 
 on money questions, the government passed resolutions 
 safeguarding similar proposals for the future; and by 
 including their financial scheme in one very compre- 
 hensive bill, carried their resolutions as regards the 
 paper duty (1861). This solution of the question is 
 interesting, not only as marking the legal ratification of 
 what had been only a prescriptive right of the Lower 
 House, but also as illustrating the speedy development 
 of democratic principles in Mr. Gladstone's nature. 
 The other question which calls for brief notice is the 
 
 i The expression was Earl Russell's. Life of Lord John Russell, by S. 
 Walpole, vol. ii. p. 344.
 
 172 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 reform, the question now lost its academic character, 
 and began to arouse eager sympathy or furious hostility; 
 for it has been alike his misfortune and his glory ever 
 to move amidst storm-clouds of controversy and mantled 
 with the dust of conflict. The conversion of Mr. Glad- 
 stone to democratic principles has therefore been an 
 event of the highest importance. His eager spirit has 
 unconsciously but inevitably drawn him far beyond his 
 cautious declaration of May, 1864, that parliamentary 
 reform ought not to be left until agitation arises, but 
 that agitation should be forestalled by wise and provi- 
 dent measures. Much as he has doubtless desired to 
 act as the serene Neptune, calming the storms of Parlia- 
 ment, his fate has doomed him to be the ^olus not only 
 of Westminster, but of the country at large. 
 
 The magnitude of his influence in 1866-1885 will be 
 obvious if we briefly estimate the aims of reformers in 
 1850-1865. Their chief efforts had been by various de- 
 vices to select for admission to the franchise only the 
 best of the unrepresented classes. For instance, the 
 bills of Lord John Russell of 1854 and of Mr. Disraeli 
 of 1859, though differing in details, 1 proposed to enfran- 
 chise only those who by their amount of income, their 
 rental, or their deposits in savings-banks, might be fairly 
 considered as possessed of energy, intelligence, or pru- 
 dence; and due weight was attached to education by 
 the admission to the franchise of all graduates of univer- 
 sities. In fact, as Disraeli said, the extension of the 
 franchise was to be not radical but lateral, importance 
 being also assigned to the variety of the classes and 
 interests to be enfranchised. 2 The measures of 1850-1865 
 
 1 That of 1854 proposed a 5 rental as admitting to the borough fran- 
 chise, and ^10 to the county franchise. 
 
 2 In Mr. Dickinson's Development of Parliament (1895), chapter ii., this 
 thought is illustrated with scholarly thoroughness and insight. It seems 
 to me, however, that the party tactics of 1866-67 are responsible for the 
 change, which the able author ascribes as ultimately due to the act of 1832.
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 173 
 
 aimed, in fact, at securing" a due balance of interests; 
 so that the old electorate, while being enlarged on all 
 sides, should not be swamped by a wholesale irruption 
 of illiterates. The difficulty of securing this due balance 
 amidst the tug- of party warfare and the vehement attacks 
 of Radicals, led by John Bright, were the chief causes 
 of the failure of the Reform Bills before 1865. 
 
 But party strife, and, still more, party expediency, were 
 soon to sweep away all the safeguards which even a 
 Radical like John Stuart Mill recognized as desirable, 
 if not essential, to well-ordered progress; and_by two 
 successive plunges England entered upon a form of 
 advanced democracy such as before 1867 no responsible 
 statesman and few thinkers would have deemed either 
 possible or desirable. 
 
 The history of the events of 1866-1867 cannot be fully 
 written until the correspondence of some of the chief 
 actors is entirely revealed to the world. At present, it 
 can only be regarded as one of the strangest and most 
 unaccountable exploits of political legerdemain. Mr. 
 Gladstone's Reform Bill of 1866 was, on the whole, one 
 of the old type, resembling its unfortunate predecessors 
 of the period 1851-1865. Postponing for the present 
 the question of redistribution of seats, he dealt only with 
 the electoral franchise, a course of action which, as in 
 1884, exposed him to sharp and ultimately successful 
 criticism. 1 He now proposed to extend the right of voting 
 to tenants paying a rental of j a year in boroughs, 
 and 14 in counties; while lodgers paying 10 a year 
 and depositors having ^50 in savings-banks were like- 
 wise to have votes. These and a few other changes 
 
 1 In view of the constitutional conflict which in 1884 was to rage around 
 the question of separating the Franchise and Redistribution Bills, it may 
 be well to note Mr. Gladstone's procedure in 1866. At first he proposed to 
 keep them entirely distinct a course ably defended by Mr. Bright; but 
 ultimately, after much discussion, he communicated the details of the Redis- 
 tribution Bill to the House, before the Franchise Bill went into committee.
 
 174 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 would enlarge the electorate by about 400,000, that is, 
 by double the numbers affected by Mr. Disraeli's pro- 
 posals of 1859 and Lord Palmerston's of 1860. It is 
 difficult, therefore, to account for the animus at once 
 aroused by these moderate proposals, except on the 
 score of party jealousy or personal dislike of Mr. Glad- 
 stone. 
 
 The measure was attacked for what it was and 
 what it was not. Mr. Laing complained that it left 
 Honiton with as much political power as Liverpool or 
 Manchester; while Mr. Lowe, developing sarcastic 
 powers which surprised the House and exasperated 
 working-men, declared that it would put power com- 
 pletely into the hands of the working-classes, who were 
 quite unqualified for this responsibility. He claimed 
 that the rise of wages and general prosperity of the 
 country placed the 10 rental well within reach of 
 thrifty and intelligent workmen, who, according to Mr. 
 Gladstone's own admission, already formed at least 
 21 per cent of the borough electorate. A reduction of 
 the limit to j would, he maintained, tend to degrade 
 the tone of elections and of parliamentary life. In his 
 reply Mr. Bright twitted Mr. Lowe with desertion from 
 the Liberal ranks, using the famous "cave of Adullam" 
 metaphor to designate the group of malcontents. But 
 ridicule and arguments were of no avail. It was in 
 vain that Mr. John Stuart Mill, now member for West- 
 minster, in a speech unsurpassed for wealth of thought, 
 disclaimed any fears concerning the enfranchisement of 
 the seven-pounders. It was in vain that Mr. Gladstone, 
 in a passage of thrilling eloquence, appealed to wider 
 influences than those of party and of Parliament "The 
 great social forces which move onward in their might 
 and majesty, and which the tumult of our debates does 
 not for a moment impede or disturb those great social 
 forces are against you : they are marshalled on our side;
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 175 
 
 and the banner which we carry in this fight, though 
 perhaps at some moment it may droop over our sinking 
 heads, yet soon again will float in the eye of heaven; 
 and it will be borne by the firm hands of the united 
 people of the three kingdoms, perhaps not to an easy, 
 but to a certain and to a not far distant victory". In 
 spite of this prophetic appeal, the second reading of the 
 bill was carried by the ominously small majority of five ! 
 "Thereupon", says an eye-witness, "there arose a 
 wild, raging, mad-brained shout. Dozens of half-frantic 
 Tories stood up in their seats and madly waved their 
 hats. The Adullamites waved their hats in sympathy; 
 and he, Lucifer, 1 the prince of the revolt, stood up 
 flushed, triumphant, and avenged, his complexion deep- 
 ened into something like bishop's purple." 
 
 Although the government now appended a very mode- 
 rate Redistribution Bill, their whole measure was wrecked 
 by an amendment in committee. Thereupon the Russell 
 ministry resigned, and for the third time Lord Derby took 
 office in the teeth of a hostile majority. Never was victory 
 more disastrous to the victors. If Gladstone threatened 
 the Tories and Adullamites with whips, Disraeli was 
 soon to chastise them with scorpions. Other causes, 
 besides the inspiring appeals of Mr. Gladstone and 
 Mr. Bright, tended to reanimate the social forces of 
 the age. A sudden commercial panic, culminating in 
 "Black Friday" (May n, 1866), roughly awakened the 
 average Briton from his years of podgy contentment to 
 a feeling that all was not well. Moreover, the exciting 
 scenes at Westminster had much impressed the people ; 
 and large meetings, almost on the scale of the Chartist 
 gatherings, were planned to agitate for reform. Scarcely 
 had the Derby ministry taken the reins of office when 
 the home secretary forbade a reform demonstration in 
 Hyde Park. It was an unwise decision. The average 
 
 1 t.e. Lowe; see Irving's Annals of Our Time, April 27, 1867.
 
 176 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Londoner hardly answers to Aristotle's definition : he is 
 not a political creature ; at least, he is so only when his 
 real or fancied rights seem threatened. Then he is up 
 in arms. That is a question which he can understand ; 
 and he then makes and unmakes ministries as readily as 
 his forefathers unseated king's who tampered with civic 
 privileges. The right of meeting in Hyde Park about 
 any and every subject was more to him than any electoral 
 reform. To Hyde Park accordingly Londoners thronged 
 on July 23, broke down the railings, and stoned the 
 policemen who endeavoured to eject them. 
 
 In ordinary circumstances the riot would have been 
 forgotten in a fortnight; but amidst the excitement 
 caused by the commercial panic, by Fenian plots, and by 
 a sharp attack of cholera, Lord Derby's weak govern- 
 ment became nervous, and wavered under the strenuous 
 attacks of John Bright and other stalwarts of reform. 1 
 The Conservative ministry was indeed in so false a 
 position that it must often have sympathized with the 
 reformers, who blamed Earl Russell for not forcing on a 
 dissolution of Parliament. We can now see that such a 
 course would have been the best, not only for the reform 
 cause, but for the honour of our political life. But 
 amidst the distractions caused by approaching war, 
 commercial panic, Fenianism, and cholera, a general 
 election in the summer of 1866 might well seem an evil 
 to be averted at all costs. 2 It may also be conceded 
 that neither Lord Derby nor Mr. Disraeli had ever 
 opposed an extension of the suffrage. Both concurred 
 in the desire of passing a "safe and moderate measure". 
 
 Nevertheless, the oddity of the situation and the whim- 
 sicalities *of their leader aroused many apprehensions 
 amongst the government minority in the Lower House, 
 
 J For Bright's influence at this time, and the indignation aroused by Lowe's 
 supposed gibes at artisans, see Mr.Vince's Life of Bright, chapter v. 
 
 * See S. Walpole's Life of Lord John Russell, ii. p. 430, for the queen's 
 letters reproaching her ministers for resigning "on a matter of detail".
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. *77 
 
 at the opening- of the session, which were not allayed by 
 Disraeli's declaration that reform ought no longer to be 
 a question determining 1 the fate of cabinets. This, at 
 any rate, portended finality after the various abortive 
 efforts of 1852-66, and a secure tenure of power to those 
 who were about to cut the Gordian knot ! Neither were 
 Tory fears quelled by the dexterous appeal to all members 
 of the House to divest themselves of party feeling- in 
 considering the resolutions now forthcoming. It soon 
 transpired that under the guise of enunciating abstract 
 truths, the ministerial resolutions were "squeezable" to 
 almost any extent; and it was with mixed indignation 
 and alarm that Lowe deprecated their discussion, "while 
 the press is hounding all on so as to bring the institu- 
 tions of the country down to the level of democracy". 
 He further upbraided the government for their almost 
 open invitation to members, "Say what you like to us, 
 only for God's sake leave us our places". By a curious 
 irony of fate, these gibes of the Adullamite chief un- 
 steadied the wavering governmental lines, and induced 
 a strategic move to the rear. Disraeli consented to 
 focus his resolutions in a "real and satisfactory" reform 
 bill, a concession which led to the resignation of Lords 
 Carnarvon and Cranborne, and General Peel. The out- 
 look seemed threatening. It was evident that one more 
 ministry was in jeopardy between Scylla and Charybdis. 
 Two courses were open : to jettison reform, which would 
 have lightened the craft, but enraged the owners and 
 the crew, besides wrecking the pilot's reputation; or to 
 allow their reform cargo to be so trimmed and readjusted 
 as to remedy the "list" and satisfy the malcontent 
 majority. The latter course was adopted, the officers 
 forthwith carrying out the orders which came from the 
 forecastle. Thus was it that the modern Ulysses saved 
 his ship. 1 
 
 1 See Malmesbury's Memoirs of an ex-Minister. "Cabinets all May on 
 
 (51410) M
 
 178 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 It remains to consider the changes thus brought 
 about. Out of 6 1 sections of the Reform Bill of 1867 
 only four were the work of the ministry, the rest were 
 so profoundly modified in committee, with the consent 
 of ministers, as to elicit from General Peel the caustic 
 remark that nothing had so little vitality as a "vital 
 point", nothing was so insecure as a "security", and 
 nothing was so elastic as the conscience of a cabinet 
 minister. 1 The sting of the satire lay in its accuracy. 
 After asserting that the government would "never intro- 
 duce household suffrage pure and simple", Lord Derby 
 and Mr. Disraeli acquiesced in its insertion, thus giving 
 effect to one of the chief claims of the old Birmingham 
 Political Union. Besides giving up the 6 rating limit 
 in boroughs, the ministry reduced the 20 limit, as 
 originally proposed for the county franchise, to 12. 
 At the dictation of the opposition, a lodger franchise of 
 10 was accepted, and the distinctions between various 
 classes of rate-payers were abolished: the provisions 
 assigning special votes to persons having ^50 in the 
 funds, 30 in a savings-bank, or paying 20 a year in 
 direct taxation, were likewise withdrawn. "Lateral" 
 extensions of the franchise, which proposed to assign 
 votes to graduates of universities, ministers of religion, 
 and members of any learned profession, were lopped off 
 by John Bright's renewed denunciation of "fancy fran- 
 chises", though philosophical Radicals had claimed such 
 franchises as a desirable set-off to the mere counting 
 of heads. Lastly, the redistribution of seats, as Lord 
 
 Reform Bill. The laissez-aller system followed by the government, trying 
 to make the best they could of it, but constantly yielding something. The 
 Conservative members seem disposed to adopt everything, and to think 
 that it is 'in for a penny, in for a pound'." It should be remembered in 
 Disraeli's favour that when urged in 1873 to take office, though with a 
 minority behind him, he refused, owing to the ignominy which so false a 
 situation entailed. On the other hand, he must have foreseen in 1867 whither 
 events were certain to lead him. 
 1 Buxton, Finance and Politics, vol. ii. p. 12, note.
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 179 
 
 Cranborne complained, effected changes fifty per cent 
 greater than had been originally contemplated, thereby 
 yielding to John Bright the victory all along the line. 
 
 As for the various "checks" which had been prominent 
 in every bill since 1852, they too had gone by the board. 
 Their only relic was a device, apparently first suggested 
 by Earl Russell, of forming "three-cornered constitu- 
 encies ". On a motion, at first rejected but finally 
 accepted by ministers, three members were allotted to 
 each of the following towns Birmingham, Leeds, Liver- 
 pool, Manchester, and, in the act for Scotland, to 
 Glasgow. This proposal was made by Mr. Laing, 
 seconded by Mr. Baines, and had the support of Mr. 
 Gladstone, but failed in the Lower House. It was re- 
 affirmed by the House of Lords, with a proviso that each 
 elector in those towns should have only two votes, so 
 that the minority would naturally return one of the three 
 members. With this clumsy and irritating expedient 
 (doomed to disappear in 1885) the friends of minority 
 representation were ill content. Mill had failed to secure 
 any approval for Mr. Hare's plan of proportionate repre- 
 sentation; and his motion in favour of according the 
 suffrage to women was also withdrawn. The differences 
 between the two Houses having been arranged, the bill 
 received the royal assent on Aug. 15, 1867. 
 
 Such was the change which enlarged the electorate 
 from 1,352,970 in 1867 to 2,243,259 in 1870, a change 
 neither loudly called for by the great masses of the 
 people nor desired by the very men who passed it. As 
 to the immorality of the tactics which led to the "leap 
 in the dark ", few will harbour any doubts. Prepared in 
 a hurry, modified beyond recognition, shuffled through 
 helter-skelter in order to "dish the Whigs", it will 
 stand to all time as a masterpiece of political trimming; 
 and, on the score of political morality, few will deny 
 some sympathy with the feelings of the Adullamite
 
 i8o The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 chief, who, looking at the measure precipitated by his 
 own headlong opposition to Mr. Gladstone's sober Act 
 of 1866, now expressed "the shame, the rage, the scorn, 
 the indignation, and the despair with which this measure 
 is viewed by every Englishman who is not a slave to 
 the trammels of party or who is not dazzled, by the 
 glare of a temporary and ignoble success ". To 
 which there came a characteristic personal retort from 
 the opportunist statesman, who had dragged the Tory 
 squires over the very brink of democratic suffrage, and 
 a declaration that he had confidence in the national 
 character of England, in her fame, in the tradition of 
 a thousand years, and in that glorious future which 
 awaited her. 
 
 Opportunism, in fact, was now to be the dominant 
 note of political life not only in Great Britain but on the 
 Continent. The years 1866-67 are the most critical in 
 the recent developments of democracy. Flouted and 
 despised ever since the mad rushes of mobs in 1848, a 
 democratic suffrage was now suddenly adopted or ac- 
 cepted by responsible statesmen of the three great 
 Teutonic states. Hostility to bureaucratic Austria 
 moved Prussia to champion the principle of universal 
 suffrage in German affairs. The victory of the northern 
 power not only ensured the acceptance of a democratic 
 suffrage in the North German Confederation, but com- 
 pelled Austria to come to terms with her long restive 
 Hungarians and other subjects. The end of the year 
 1867 accordingly witnessed the adoption, more or less 
 reluctant, of parliamentary representation in all the 
 lands between the Baltic and the Adriatic. 1 
 
 The resemblance between British and continental de- 
 velopments was of course only superficial, though it 
 
 iCf. Bismarck's admission "I accepted universal suffrage, but with 
 repugnance, as a Frankfurt tradition" (i.e. of 1848). Busch, Our Chan- 
 cellor, Eng. Ed. vol. ii. p. 196.
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 181 
 
 may be questioned whether the imminence of the Austro- 
 Prussian war at midsummer, 1866, by rendering" a dis- 
 solution of our Parliament hazardous or impossible, did 
 not contribute to the strange events leading up to the 
 Conservative Reform Bill. In any case, the world now 
 saw with cynical surprise the adoption of democratic 
 franchises at Berlin, Westminster, and Vienna by the 
 very statesmen who previously had offered the most 
 strenuous opposition. In reviewing these events one can- 
 not but feel the truth of Canning's adage "Those who 
 oppose improvement because it is innovation, may one 
 day have to submit to innovation which is not improve- 
 ment". For whatever views may be entertained as to 
 the merits of the franchises granted in these years, they 
 were undoubtedly conceded from sheer expediency, and, 
 what is more important, without any of that preparation 
 in the lives of the respective nations which is the very 
 life-blood of worthy citizenship. Changes, which might 
 have wrought nothing but good if they had come as the 
 natural result of civic training, were hastily flung to 
 astonished peoples as the result of partisan or diplomatic 
 manceuvrings for place and power. In this fact we may 
 discern one cause of the comparative failure of democ- 
 racy to attain that higher moral development, which 
 has ever been the goal of its worthiest champions; and 
 possibly the want of any vital relation between civic 
 duty and the new political privileges may account for 
 the swift relapses into indifference which have so often 
 recurred when the material interests of the newly-en- 
 franchised classes have received temporary satisfaction. 
 It will be alike impossible and undesirable to do 
 more than notice the salient features of the memorable 
 measures which ensued after the downfall of Mr. Dis- 
 raeli's ministry in 1868. Coming into power with a 
 majority of 128, Mr. Gladstone held a more commanding 
 position than had been enjoyed by any premier since
 
 182 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 1832, and he now proceeded to give effect to many 
 demands which had been postponed during the suprem- 
 acy of Lords Palmerston and Derby. The two first 
 great measures were prompted by a desire to remedy 
 the chief grievances still felt by the majority of the Irish 
 people, namely the supremacy of an alien church and 
 the pressure of an unjust land tenure. The disestablish- 
 ment of the Church of Ireland removed the last relic of 
 that Protestant ascendency, which had been the central 
 principle of British policy towards the sister island from 
 the time of William III.'s conquest down to the con- 
 cession of civic rights to Roman Catholics in 1829. Mr. 
 Gladstone's act of 1869 completed the edifice of religious 
 and civic equality, of which the Duke of Wellington and 
 Sir Robert Peel had rather reluctantly reared the frame- 
 work. 
 
 Equally important was the endeavour of the new 
 ministry to heal the agrarian troubles of Ireland by 
 extending to all parts the plan of compensation for im- 
 provements which was enjoyed by tenants in Ulster. 
 The Irish Land Act of 1870, which passed both Houses 
 of Parliament by large majorities in the Commons by 
 442 to ii is the first important effort at remedying 
 immemorial grievances in land tenure so as to ensure 
 something like a partnership between landlord and 
 tenant. The act may be considered as a concession 
 to that spirit of equality which has been increasingly 
 applied to agrarian affairs ever since the first French 
 Revolution. But it was also a necessity to establish a 
 modus vivendi between an unpopular and largely non- 
 resident landlord class, and a fast-increasing peasantry 
 which clung to a soil that never could adequately support 
 them. The process has been pushed on by imperious 
 economic forces. Every railway driven into the virgin 
 prairies of the Missouri, Saskatchewan, and La Plata 
 has sharpened competition for the corn-growers and
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 183 
 
 graziers of the Old World; and had not Parliament 
 striven to readjust the relations between landlord and 
 tenant, not only in Ireland but in Great Britain, our 
 agriculture might have fallen into the state of that of 
 ancient Italy. 
 
 Of the other great measures of the Gladstone ministry, 
 two only need be noticed here. The Ballot Act, passed 
 in spite of strong opposition by the Upper House, gave 
 effect to secrecy of voting, for which Mr. Grote, and 
 after him the Chartists, had agitated in vain. The 
 opposition was ostensibly based either on sentimental 
 objections to secrecy, in which some Liberals, among 
 them John Stuart Mill, concurred; or on the more 
 serious contention that personation at elections would 
 be easier than heretofore. The new system has, how- 
 ever, on the whole proved to work remarkably well, and 
 has justified the persistence of its early champions. 
 Another of the "points" of the People's Charter was 
 hereby gained. 
 
 In its far-reaching social results, the Act for providing 
 Elementary Education may be pronounced to be the most 
 important act of the whole period. Other measures 
 altered the balance of political power; but none has 
 entered so intimately into the life of the people, or borne 
 results so fruitful and beneficial, as the act passed by 
 Mr. Forster in 1870. Imperfect in some details though 
 it was, this great measure for the first time put education 
 within the reach of every cottager, supplementing, with- 
 out destroying, the work which the National and British 
 schools had nobly endeavoured to carry on. The ques- 
 tion of religious instruction, which had been the crux in 
 and after 1843, was now solved by the Cowper-Temple 
 clauses in a compromise which has successfully resisted 
 the immediate onslaughts of Mr. Miall and the Non- 
 conformists, as well as clerical attacks in recent years. 
 Now, at last, the people of the United Kingdom gained
 
 184 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 that modicum of "schoolmasters' education" for which 
 Carlyle had passionately pleaded in Past and Present. 
 
 It must be confessed that Mr. Forster's measure was 
 to some extent the result of middle-class apprehensions. 
 In the midst of his invective against the Reform Act 
 of 1867, Lowe had exclaimed that it was thenceforth 
 absolutely necessary to compel our future masters to 
 learn their letters, and that education must be pressed 
 on without delay for the peace of the country. In 
 an exaggerated form he expressed the fears of many 
 thinking men of an earlier day, when the teachings of 
 Owen and Hodgkin were agitating the working-classes. 
 Those apprehensions were curiously expressed by John 
 Stuart Mill. In his zeal for education, the philosopher 
 declared that he rejoiced at the power which those level- 
 ling notions about property still had over artisans, because 
 fear and fear alone would compel the middle classes 
 seriously to take up the education question in order to 
 dispel such fallacious notions. These fears were doubt- 
 less a trifle antiquated in 1867; but the notorious trade- 
 union outrages at Sheffield showed that there was still 
 grave danger in allowing our labouring population to 
 grow up in brutalizing ignorance. 
 
 The impressionable character of an untrained populace 
 was rarely more manifested than in the speedy decline 
 in popularity of the Gladstone cabinet in 1871-1873. 
 Various external causes have of course been plausibly 
 assigned for this swing of the pendulum. The distrac- 
 tions caused by the Franco-German War, the commence- 
 ment of those senseless menaces from Berlin which have 
 sown discord between us and our Teutonic cousins, the 
 rather tame surrender by the Gladstone ministry of the 
 Black Sea clauses of the Treaty of Paris in deference to 
 Russian demands, its complaisance to the United States 
 over the exorbitant awards in the Alabama arbitration, 
 all these naturally reawakened our national spirit, which
 
 The Reform Bills of 1866-1867. 185 
 
 had lain dormant under the cyclonic activity of domestic 
 legislation. Indeed, the phenomenal reforming- zeal of 
 the years 1868-1872 tended to weld various vested in- 
 terests on to the shattered Conservative party. Patriots 
 enraged at the degradation of Britain to the rank of a 
 second-rate power, employers of labour who feared the 
 rising demands of their "hands", military officers fuming 
 at the abolition of the time-honoured "purchase system", 
 naval critics of Admiralty maladministration, tax-payers 
 incensed at the increase of charges imposed by army and 
 educational reforms, Nonconformist ultras alienated by 
 the Education Act, clerics irritated by the abolition of 
 religious tests at our universities, Irish Nationalists 
 stung to the quick by the Peace Preservation Act, all 
 were swept into the opposition drag-net. It was in vain 
 for Mr. Gladstone to declare, shortly before the dissolu- 
 tion of Parliament, that if he were returned to power, 
 he would abolish the income-tax. Mr. Disraeli made 
 exactly the same bid for power, and skilfully flattered 
 the amour propre of the nation which Gladstone's pacific 
 policy had ruffled. Such were the chief causes under- 
 mining the popularity of the powerful Liberal adminis- 
 tration. Their result was seen in the general election of 
 1874, which sent up to Westminster 350 Conservatives, 
 as against 244 Liberals and 58 Home Rulers. 
 
 Looking back calmly on the five years of the Gladstone 
 administration, it must be considered as falsifying the 
 worst fears of its opponents no less than disappointing 
 the enthusiastic hopes of its supporters. On the one 
 hand, the fears of the old Whigs, who regarded Demos 
 as an insatiable Caliban, that must be taught to read 
 and write lest perchance he might rend Prospero and 
 engulf at once his learning and his goods, were soon 
 seen to be the result of nightmare. Prospero and 
 Miranda remained unharmed. Taxation was reduced, 
 and wealth advanced with giant strides. The policy of
 
 i86 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 systematic bleeding- of the wealthy had not yet found 
 favour with any but the smallest section of the Radicals; 
 and these were utterly outnumbered by the men of pro- 
 perty, who still retained their old predominance in the 
 Commons. Just as the results of the Reform Act of 
 1832 were toned down by the personal ascendency of 
 Earl Grey, Lord Melbourne, and Lord Palmerston, so 
 the results of the transition to democracy, accomplished 
 in 1867, were mitigated by the ascendency of Mr. Glad- 
 stone and of colleagues who represented still more fully 
 the old Liberalism. Owing to this fact, to the distractions 
 caused by Irish and continental troubles, and to the 
 general prosperity of the country, the enthusiasm for 
 political change speedily cooled. And yet, with the ex- 
 ception of the disestablishment of the Irish Church, no 
 one of Mr. Gladstone's Acts can be called destructive. 
 Neither were the rights of property trenched upon except 
 in some provisions of the Irish Land Act, which did 
 little more than apply to other parts of Ireland the tenant 
 right of Ulster. The legislation of 1868-1873 was sober, 
 constructive, and on a level with the highest traditions 
 of the past. 
 
 Chapter XII. 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 
 
 It must be confessed by all unprejudiced observers that 
 the Reform Act of 1867 inaugurated a period of unrest 
 and political instability. As the competition between 
 parties for the enjoyment of popular favours has become 
 keener, every general election has aroused boundless 
 hopes of the felicity to be bestowed on the nation by the 
 new administration. 
 
 " Man never is, but always to be, blest."
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 187 
 
 If Pope's verse is true of his complacent age, how much 
 more is it correct of our own, distracted by alluring" ideals 
 and warring programmes ! This is at once its glory and 
 its danger. Hope has energized masses of the people 
 that previously were sunk in torpor; but it has also 
 swayed them heedlessly from side to side in search of 
 the enchanted fruit of happiness temptingly dangled 
 before their eyes. This is a natural, perhaps inevitable, 
 result of recent reform acts. The admission to the 
 electorate of classes that necessarily know little about the 
 limitations which beset the action of the most benevolent 
 law-makers, and still less about the complexity of our 
 national interests, has tended to magnify the hopes of 
 the nation, and also to deepen the disappointment which 
 almost inevitably follows. Competition for the votes of 
 the newly enfranchised leads to the cultivation of the art 
 of programme making, and the successful claimants for 
 power come into office weighted with an impossible 
 programme and a discordant majority. 
 
 After five years of legislative activity, the benefits of 
 which few will now contest, Mr. Gladstone saw the 
 majority of 128, which supported him in 1869, trans- 
 formed by the general election of 1874 into a minority 
 of IO6. 1 His successor, Mr. Disraeli, was to experience 
 the same fate, the general election of 1880 changing the 
 majority of 106 into a minority of 106, if the Home Rule 
 vote be omitted from the comparison. As I shall show 
 in the next chapter, the agrarian measures promised by 
 Mr. Gladstone in 1885, and the extension of household 
 suffrage to the rural districts, portended a continuance 
 of Liberal predominance, until the Home Rule Bill cut 
 athwart the plane of political life. It can hardly be said 
 to have restored the balance of political power, for it 
 
 1 Reckoned as between Liberals and Conservatives only. The appearance 
 of 58 Home Rulers, definitely organized as a party, confuses the statistics 
 when compared with those of 1868.
 
 i88 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 would be absurd to use a metaphor which implies 
 stability to denote a series of oscillations. The only 
 regularity in our modern political life is the almost 
 monotonous periodicity of its changes. The appended 
 foot-note will illustrate more clearly than any description 
 the instability of our modern political system, which may 
 be realized by placing in contrast the conditions which 
 obtained before the Reform Acts of 1867 and i832. a 
 Roughly speaking, the period 1714-1793 may be de- 
 scribed as one of unbroken predominance for the Whig 
 governing families, disturbed by factious feuds, but not 
 marked by any changes based on principle. The advent 
 of militant democracy in France dissolved for ever the 
 hitherto triumphant Whig oligarchy; and the Tories, 
 rallied by the younger Pitt to the support of the throne, 
 enjoyed a tenure of power, which was broken only by 
 the reform movement of 1831-32. The great electoral 
 change of 1832 closed the era of almost Chinese immo- 
 bility, and ministerial changes followed with perplexing 
 rapidity; but these changes, when not merely of a 
 
 1 The following are the results of the general elections of 1833-1895 : 
 
 Liberals, &c. Conservatives. Home Rulers. 
 
 1833 
 
 ... 486 ... 
 
 ... 176 
 273 
 
 
 1837 
 
 348 
 
 
 
 1841, 
 
 ... 286 ... 
 
 ... 367 
 
 
 1847 
 1852, 
 
 i857, 
 1859. 
 
 ... 3 2 S - 
 
 ... 3IS - 
 
 ... 366 ... 
 
 ... 348 ... 
 
 { 
 
 I 
 
 ... 287 
 
 3S 
 
 of whom 105 
 were Peelites 
 of whom 40 
 were Peelites 
 
 1866, 
 
 .. 361 . 
 
 204 
 
 
 1868 
 
 ... 393 
 
 ... 265 
 
 
 
 
 35 
 
 
 1880 
 
 ... 349 ... 
 
 243 
 
 
 1885 
 
 ... 335 ... 
 
 249 
 
 
 TRA / Liberal 
 1886, i H R , 
 
 
 - 394 { 
 
 including 78 
 Lib. Unionists 
 
 58 
 
 60 
 
 86 
 
 Liberal > ^ 
 Home Rulers f 274
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 189 
 
 personal nature, were often due to the evenness of the 
 parliamentary struggle, especially in the years 1847 to 
 1866, when the electors enfranchised by the measure of 
 1832 had settled down into the parties to which they 
 had most affinity. On comparing the strength of parties 
 in the years 1847-1866 with the figures of the next twenty 
 years, it is impossible to avoid the conclusion that each 
 extension of the suffrage has increased the uncertainties 
 of political life. Whether these changes will ultimately 
 tend to the re-establishment of a new equilibrium, as 
 happened after the electors enfranchised in 1832 had 
 become inured to the responsibilities and disappointments 
 of the political game, time alone can show. 1 
 
 I have already suggested some causes, both internal and 
 external, for the instability which marks the years since 
 Mr. Disraeli's Reform Act. On the whole, I am inclined 
 to assign less importance than is usually done to the 
 external causes, that is, to the opposition of "vested 
 interests " to which a defeated party is ever wont com- 
 placently to ascribe its disaster. It seems impossible 
 that so great a change could have been brought about 
 merely by a combination of vested interests, especially 
 as these had always been more or less hostile to Mr. 
 Gladstone's programme. It was perfectly well known 
 what the Liberal ministry would attempt; and only in 
 foreign and Irish affairs were any surprises in store for 
 the electorate. It is true that the personnel of the Glad- 
 stone ministry was not perfect. Mr. Ayrton's lofty 
 pretensions, Robert Lowe's stinging tongue (not to 
 speak of his match tax), even the irritating Aristides-like 
 
 a The instability of opinion will be more strikingly obvious when it is 
 remembered that the increase in the size of the average constituency has 
 been enormous. This ought to have contributed to stability, and doubtless 
 it will do so when political opinion has solidified. In the old rotten boroughs 
 the transference of a score of votes frequently turned the scale. Now it 
 generally needs a thousand or more ; but the transfer of the thousand votes 
 is apparently quite as easy as that of the score used to be.
 
 190 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 quality of Mr. Gladstone's character, all contributed to 
 worry and weary the public mind. But then the people 
 must have been singularly impressionable, not to say 
 fickle, to have allowed such trifles to weigh in the balance 
 with the undeniable benefits received from the ministry. 
 Nor were these boons only prospective. Taxation had 
 been lightened to the extent of ^"12,000,000, and the 
 national debt had been reduced by ^26, 000,000. Trade 
 had improved. Coming to power shortly after a com- 
 mercial crisis, the administration left the country in a 
 blaze of prosperity, which ought to have counterbalanced 
 Disraeli's gibe that ministers lived in a blaze of apology. 
 But the country forgot the boons and remembered only 
 the jests Several ministries have fallen victims to bad 
 harvests or commercial crises. It was reserved for the 
 year 1874 to witness the growth of the nation's wealth 
 by leaps and bounds, and the increasing unpopularity of 
 an administration which had largely contributed to that 
 prosperity. 
 
 The fundamental cause of the revulsion in popular 
 feeling seems to me to reside in the unpreparedness of 
 the new electorate for its duties. It was certainly not 
 educated up to the level of Mr. Gladstone's reforming 
 zeal. Indeed, an examination of the legislation of 
 1869-1873 proves its motive power to have resided, not 
 so much in the people's will as in the convictions of the 
 premier and a few of his colleagues. The British people 
 can stand "heroic legislation" only in small doses. 
 John Bright expressed the feelings of the average man 
 when, surprised at Gladstone's decision to bring in the 
 great Education Bill only two days after the introduction 
 of the complex Irish Land Bill, he exclaimed that it was 
 like attempting to drive six omnibuses at once through 
 Temple Bar. Yet the feat was accomplished ; and what 
 is far more, the ministry carried through Parliament every 
 important item in its programme except the ill-starred
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 191 
 
 Dublin University Bill. The pace was certainly trying 
 to John Bull. But he had been warned of it before he 
 paid his fare. The journey ended safely, prosperously, 
 even happily, as it seemed ; and yet he at once transferred 
 his custom to the opposition coach. It is difficult to 
 believe that he was the same personage as before the 
 change of 1867; and indeed a comparison of the election 
 results before and after 1867 shows how important was 
 the change then effected. The constancy to party ties, 
 which had marked the previous generation, was replaced 
 by a habit of "voting agin' the government", whether 
 it does or does not carry out its programme. In 1869- 
 1874 the ministry apparently did too much. The country 
 was so surfeited with reforms that the legislation of those 
 years, which was expected to win the eternal gratitude 
 of the newly enfranchised, aroused only a passing senti- 
 ment. The people most benefited by the reforms were 
 as yet too pot-bound and callous to appreciate them at 
 their true value; and the very Ballot Act, which, it was 
 supposed, would add to the political power of the pro- 
 letariate and attach it to the Liberal party, served as a 
 screen for its ingratitude in the election of 1874. It is 
 not surprising that Mr. Gladstone soon decided to resign 
 the thankless position of a political leader for the less 
 transient charms of literary life, until the forlorn cries 
 of a distressed Eastern people again appealed to his 
 humanity, and called him once again into the arena of 
 party strife. 
 
 Mr. Gladstone has not been richly dowered by nature 
 with that social tact or worldly wisdom which compre- 
 hends not only the greatness but the littleness of man- 
 kind. He could not see that the country wanted rest 
 and comfort, pleasure and prestige, rather than epoch- 
 marking reforms. Mr. Disraeli understood the needs 
 of the time. The artisan class wanted a few practical 
 measures such as would add to the comforts of life.
 
 192 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 These the new premier granted by his factory legisla- 
 tion, by Mr. Cross's Artisans' Dwellings Act (1875), 
 and by the act for the proper supervision of Friendly 
 Societies. He thus strove to emulate the enlightened 
 example of Henri IV. of France, who boasted that in his 
 time every peasant could have a fowl in his pot. 
 
 But side by side with this pot au feu policy, Disraeli 
 cherished vaster designs. He saw that wealthy England 
 was weary of the narrowness of the Manchester school 
 and of the humiliations entailed by its "peace at any 
 price" policy. His judgment was correct. The middle 
 classes were slowly but surely outgrowing the "little 
 England" ideas of the days of Cobden. A pacific 
 foreign policy and devotion to domestic legislation were 
 doubtless desirable when England was in the throes of 
 her industrial revolution, and was distracted by desperate 
 strikes or Chartist demonstrations. But those days 
 were past. The worst grievances had been healed. 
 Free-trade had brought cheap bread to the artisan and 
 abundant orders to the manufacturer and merchant. 
 The very success of the Manchester school in expanding 
 our commerce passed the death sentence on the "little 
 England" policy which was needful in the "forties". 
 The splendid growth of Greater Britain reawakened in 
 the race those larger aspirations towards a world-wide 
 Commonwealth which had lain dormant since Waterloo ; 
 and now, when the German Empire sprang full-armed 
 into life, and blatant militarism became the dominant 
 note of European politics, there was imperious need that 
 the mother land should turn her gaze seawards, and 
 should protect her defenceless colonies and merchantmen 
 against the jealousies, rivalries, and possible assaults of 
 mail-clad continental powers. This phase in our 
 national development was natural and inevitable. Our 
 wealth had provoked envy which was far from being 
 appeased by Mr. Gladstone's pacific concessions. The
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 193 
 
 nation therefore demanded precautionary measures and 
 a stiffer tone in our foreign policy. Surely, though un- 
 consciously, the nation was swinging back from what I 
 have ventured to call the introspective or domestic phase 
 of life to the expansive phase which must now and again 
 mark the growth of any vigorous insular race. How- 
 ever guilty of ingratitude towards individuals, the nation 
 must satisfy the needs of its existence. Those needs 
 were for the time imperialist ; and Disraeli seemed about 
 to satisfy them by his "spirited foreign policy". 
 
 The two chief aims, then, of the new premier were to 
 promote comfort at home by soothing little instalments 
 of social legislation and to enhance the nation's prestige 
 abroad. For a time this deft admixture of the prosaic 
 and the sublime seemed to give general satisfaction. 
 The Artisans' Dwellings Act facilitated the destruction 
 of fever-breeding dens and the erection of healthier 
 dwellings. 1 The Friendly Societies Act, while not in- 
 terfering unduly with the working of provident societies, 
 provided some safeguards against the frauds and follies 
 which had wrecked so many of these valuable institu- 
 tions. The Factory Acts of 1875 and 1878, and other 
 measures regulating the status of workers, bore witness 
 to the honest intentions of the ministry, and of the 
 premier, who in his novel Sybil had expressed his desire 
 to rally the artisans under the banner of some modern 
 Simon de Montfort. While these measures appealed to 
 Saxon domesticity, the premier's foreign policy had that 
 touch of romance which might have been expected from 
 the author of Tancred. Disraeli knew that under John 
 Bull's prosaic exterior there lurk ideas, if only they can 
 
 J A practical result is Corporation Street, Birmingham, which, by the 
 energy and foresight of the town-council (especially of Mr. Chamberlain), 
 was driven through a wretched slum, and provided not only a fine thorough- 
 fare, but ample accommodation for the hitherto badly-housed artisans. See 
 Dolman's Municipalities at Work, p. 12. For some objections to the act 
 of 1875 see Dr. Cunningham's Politics and Economics, p. 171.
 
 ip4 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 be made vocal by some skilful interpreter. The race 
 which had produced Sidney, Spenser, Drake, Essex, 
 Raleigh, Marlborough, Clive, Wolfe, and Chinese 
 Gordon, could not be lacking in world-subduing quali- 
 ties. These qualities must now be reawakened to con- 
 solidate the dominions which Britons had won. That 
 pride in the empire which moved even the gloomy poet 
 of Olney to impassioned verse must again play its part 
 in the history of the race. Its imperial instincts must 
 assert their supremacy over the huckstering side of the 
 Saxon nature. 
 
 It seemed that the United Kingdom had secured the 
 ideal policy which satisfied its duality of interests, re- 
 conciling the desire of comfort in the cottage with the 
 passion for world-wide renown, combining the prose of 
 domestic interests with the glamour of eastern romance, 
 the libertas of the Saxon with the imperium of the 
 Roman. How came it that even the political art and 
 rhetorical felicity of a Disraeli failed to wed these ideals 
 in a lasting union? 
 
 In brief, the prose of the western hemisphere and the 
 passions of the eastern world conspired to destroy the 
 new policy, by pitting against each other our industrial 
 and imperial interests. The United Kingdom is the Janus 
 of the modern world : it is the meeting-place of the east 
 and the west. Politically it must perforce turn east- 
 wards to safeguard its Australasian and Indian posses- 
 sions. Industrially its gaze is turned westwards by the 
 gigantic industrial and agricultural developments of the 
 New World. There is the eternal conflict of interests 
 which must ever tax the powers of British statesman- 
 ship. They have never been so tested as in the years 
 1874-1880, which were rendered memorable by un- 
 equalled activity in the peaceful development of the 
 North American continent, and by popular commotions 
 in the usually immobile east. Let us briefly examine
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 195 
 
 the concurrent effects of these events in English political 
 life. 
 
 Every reduction in the cost of iron and steel, every 
 triumph of the engineer, whether in the construction of 
 railroads or of steamships, has tended to annihilate 
 distance, to place the settler of Nebraska on almost 
 even terms with the farmer of Norfolk in competing for 
 the London market, and thereby to reduce old English 
 estates to something like the value of prairie land. For 
 political and economic reasons which need not here be 
 detailed, the results of our free-trade policy were only 
 fully felt after 1870. Their pressure was most severe 
 during Disraeli's tenure of power, when successive bad 
 harvests at home threatened to involve landlord, farmer, 
 and labourer in one common ruin. The agrarian crisis, 
 which had long been foreseen by Free-traders, was thus 
 swiftly and acutely developed. It seemed to portend the 
 same results for the United Kingdom as those which 
 were fatal to the agriculture of ancient Italy, converting 
 its fertile plains into a wilderness of great estates, a 
 purgatory to the cultivators and a paradise for the 
 wealthy. Under the selfish Roman oligarchy free-trade 
 desolated the country districts, driving the peasants into 
 overcrowded cities, where they subsisted on government 
 doles of Libyan corn. Was it to have an analogous 
 result on the life of England and Ireland? Considered 
 merely on economic grounds, our agricultural position 
 was almost as serious as that of Rome in the days of the 
 Gracchi. Our land system was as little suited to with- 
 stand the strain of American competition as was that of 
 ancient Rome when the cheap corn of Sicily, Libya, and 
 Egypt began to flood her markets. But the moral and 
 political conditions were altogether different. The House 
 of Lords had by a considerable majority ratified the 
 abolition of the Corn -laws, an act which has received 
 all too scanty a recognition from partisan historians.
 
 196 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Not only had the peers of the United Kingdom by that 
 concession exposed their rent-rolls to the full force of 
 foreign competition, they had also assented to Mr. 
 Gladstone's Irish Land Act of 1870; and now, when its 
 provisions were rendered obsolete by the onward rush 
 of American competition, many of the Irish landlords 
 accorded substantial reductions of rent. The same 
 action was still more generally followed by landlords in 
 Great Britain to necessitous tenants behaviour which 
 stands in noble contrast to that of the senators of 
 ancient Rome, who clung to every shred of legal right 
 and hounded agrarian reformers to death. 
 
 Yet, in spite of the generally enlightened and open- 
 handed conduct of British landlords, an agricultural 
 crisis so acute as that which began after 1875 inevitably 
 embittered class relations, and fostered a democratic 
 spirit such as never before had invaded the rural dis- 
 tricts. It was in vain that Parliament passed the Agri- 
 cultural Holdings Act (1875), granting compensation to 
 tenants for unexhausted improvements. The measure 
 was permissive, rendering such payment compulsory 
 only where both landlord and tenant had agreed to 
 abide by its provisions ; and many landlords, scared by 
 the prospect of increasing demands on a diminishing 
 rent-roll, contracted themselves out of its operation. It 
 was in vain that the premier used all the resources of 
 his facile logic to prove that the land might and must 
 support landlord, tenant, and labourer, not to speak of 
 tithe-receiver. For once he spoke to deaf ears, even 
 in his own Buckinghamshire. As distress deepened 
 and taxation increased, class hostility developed in 
 intensity. Farmers demanded a revision of land-laws 
 in the interests of tenants, remembering full well that 
 Cobden and Bright had demanded such a revision as 
 necessitated by the increased area of foreign competition. 
 Above all, they pressed for relief from the game-laws,
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 197 
 
 under which the landlords' sport seemed to be regarded 
 as prior to the tenants' interests. Now, on these topics 
 Cobdenites had long been insisting- in vain. At last, 
 under the pressure of distress, the bucolic mind gave 
 heed; and farmers began to look to the Liberal party 
 for agrarian reforms more drastic than any which could 
 be expected from the holders of power. 
 
 But farmers were not the only class that was induced 
 by the pressure of American competition to coquet with 
 democratic ideas. The movement began to agitate even 
 the stolid agricultural labourers, who looked with envy 
 on the position gained by trade-unions for town artisans. 
 For the first time since the collapse of the Agricultural 
 Labourers' Unions in 1834-1835, Hodge began to be- 
 come a political creature and talk about his rights an 
 important development, which, as will shortly appear, 
 prepared the way for the agrarian policy of the Liberal 
 party in I884. 1 
 
 Even more serious were the results of foreign competi- 
 tion in the economic and social life of Ireland. Despite 
 the well-meant efforts of Mr. Gladstone to readjust the 
 relations of landlord and tenant, those relations became 
 ever more strained. Differences of creed and of race 
 often separated landlord and tenant in that unhappy 
 island, where there were few industries except agricul- 
 ture for a population whose natural increase was the 
 greatest in Europe. Every force which could make for 
 social unrest was therefore at work in Ireland, when a 
 prominent member of the Home Rule party saw in the 
 agrarian question a means not only of shattering land- 
 lordism, but of dissolving the union between Great 
 
 1 The increased importance attached to the extension of household suffrage 
 to the rural districts may be measured by the votes of the House of Commons 
 on the subject. In 1872 it was rejected by 148 to 70; in 1873 i* was talked 
 out; in 1874 it was rejected by 287 to 173; in 1875 by 268 to 166; in 1876 
 by 264 to 165; in 1877 by 274 to 218; in 1878 by 271 to 219; in 1879 by 291 
 to 226.
 
 198 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Britain and Ireland. In October, 1879, Mr. Davitt formed 
 the Land League, which forthwith commenced a sys- 
 tematic campaign against the payment of rent, and 
 before long enabled the Home Rule party almost to 
 snatch a victory. 
 
 Such were the chief influences of American competition 
 on the agriculture and society of the United Kingdom, 
 tending inevitably to the modification, if not the Ameri- 
 canizing of our laws and institutions. But while our 
 patriarchal customs were exposed to an economic strain 
 unparalleled in the history of the modern world, the 
 storm-cloud of war began to appear in the East, small 
 at first, but speedily spreading over the whole sky. A 
 famine of unsurpassed severity in India in 1876-1878 
 taxed alike the powers of the Indian government and 
 the generosity of the British public. By an unfortunate 
 coincidence the new title of Empress of India, recently 
 accorded by Parliament to Her Majesty, was officially 
 proclaimed at Delhi on New Year's Day, 1877, when 
 large tracts of India were already devastated by the 
 famine ; and a title which was meant as a spirited retort 
 to the advances of Russia in Turkestan, was at that 
 time deemed by many to be the cynical avowal of an 
 ambitious and heartless imperialism. This impression 
 was deepened by the Afghan policy of the Indian 
 government, which embroiled us in a serious war, and 
 hopelessly deranged the finances of our great eastern 
 dependency. People began to ask whether an almost 
 bankrupt possession, which embroiled us in constant 
 wars, gave any adequate return for the efforts of the 
 " weary Titan". 
 
 These searchings of heart were rendered more acute 
 
 by the Earl of Beaconsfield's 1 policy in the Eastern 
 
 Question. Into the merits of that policy it is impossible 
 
 here to enter ; but now that the Bulgarian atrocities have 
 
 1 Mr. Disraeli received this title in August, 1876.
 
 The Ebb and Flow of Public Opinion. 199 
 
 paled before infinitely greater horrors, it may be safely 
 admitted as a non-partisan statement, that the conscience 
 of the British people was deeply shocked at the deter- 
 mination of the ministry to uphold the integrity of the 
 Turkish Empire on the score of British interests. There 
 was a general feeling of repugnance, not only at the 
 Turcophil policy of the government, but at the imperial 
 interests which seemed to call for that policy. The feel- 
 ing was honourable to the conscience of our people, even 
 if it was expressed by Mr. Gladstone in his Midlothian 
 campaign with the zeal of a prophet rather than the 
 foresight of a statesman. However much the imperial- 
 ism of Lord Beaconsfield may be criticised in regard to 
 details, there can be little doubt now that he laid down 
 the general lines of policy which must be followed by 
 the British race if it is to hold a foremost place in the 
 world. 
 
 But even those who admit his prescience as to the 
 broader issues of imperialism may still criticise his 
 Indian or his Turcophil policy, either on the score of 
 morality or of its inexpedience under existing circum- 
 stances. There can be little doubt, indeed, that his 
 action on these questions contributed largely to the 
 revival of the Liberal party in 1878-1880; but it may 
 be doubted whether the dreary succession of wars and 
 rumours of wars would alone have hurled the Conserva- 
 tives from power, had not our resources been grievously 
 depleted by the agrarian troubles previously described. 
 The depression in trade and agriculture, and the war 
 expenditure for the East and in Zululand, were conjointly 
 responsible for a series of deficits which in 1880 amounted 
 in all to ; 1 0,000,000,* and that too in spite of consider- 
 able additions to taxation. The people, who had pre- 
 viously grown accustomed to magnificent surpluses, 
 visited their resentment on the government, which, after 
 
 1 Puxton, Finance and Politics, ii. p. 256,
 
 200 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 proclaiming 1 its championship of social legislation, left 
 the classes mutually suspicious, trade and agriculture 
 in the depths of stagnation, and our resources crippled 
 by a heavy expenditure. It is said that the general 
 election of 1880 was decided by the unpopular foreign 
 policy of the government and the glowing oratory of 
 Mr. Gladstone. To the present writer these causes seem 
 inadequate to account for the swift change in public 
 opinion. Probably the agrarian difficulties, and the de- 
 pression of trade which they entailed, were of far greater 
 potency. The pot au feu policy of the government had 
 been a failure owing to the causes previously described ; 
 and farmers now for once joined hands with the town 
 artisans in helping to power the party which promised 
 peace abroad and drastic agrarian legislation at home. 
 This combination of various classes of malcontents pos- 
 sessed few elements of stability; but it sufficed (as was 
 the case in 1874) to overturn a government and to 
 inaugurate a new period of legislative activity and social 
 unrest, the chief features of which will be noticed in the 
 next chapter. 
 
 Chapter XIII. 
 The Third Reform Act. 
 
 In a speech delivered at Brighton amidst the turmoil 
 aroused by the third Reform Act, Sir George (then Mr.) 
 Trevelyan revealed the origin of the demand for the 
 assimilation of the borough and county franchise, of 
 which he had been the most persistent parliamentary 
 champion. He said that his attention had been riveted 
 on this question in 1868 by the earnest appeals of his 
 artisan constituents in the Border burghs. They had 
 recently been admitted to the suffrage by the second
 
 The Third Reform Act. 201 
 
 Reform Act, which, though according- votes to every 
 householder in a parliamentary borough, still kept the 
 limit of the county "occupation" franchise as high as 
 a ;i2 rental. They strongly urged their member to 
 turn his attention to the work of removing this in- 
 equality, by which nearly all members of their class were 
 excluded from the county franchise. He was led to 
 devote his special energies to this task by his admiration 
 of the motives which inspired the request "This pro- 
 posal began in unselfishness, and it has been unselfish 
 and disinterested to the very end ". The incident proves 
 that the third movement for reform, which led up to the 
 Acts of 1884-1885, owed its origin to the feelings of the 
 working-classes as largely as that of 1830-1832. 
 
 The second Reform Act had no distinctively demo- 
 cratic origin; but the party manoeuvres which carried it 
 led up to a compromise that no one pretended to regard 
 as final. The resulting anomalies were scarcely less 
 irritating than those which it removed or mitigated. 
 The electoral device which, while according to five 
 large towns three members apiece, really reduced their 
 parliamentary voting power to one, was denounced in 
 scathing terms by the veteran member for Birmingham; 
 and while the " three-cornered " trick irritated the Radi- 
 cals of the great towns, the inequalities between the 
 urban and rural franchise served to awaken the artisans 
 of suburbs and farm labourers to the fact that they too 
 had a real grievance. Why should every holder of a 
 rickety tenement in a parliamentary borough have a 
 vote, while the artisans renting 11 cottages in Peck- 
 ham or Ancoats, and the small tenant-holders of Kent 
 and Midlothian, were still excluded from the suffrage? 
 The inequality was exasperating, even to a people which 
 was not imbued with the continental mania for political 
 symmetry. Reformers, moreover, could cite the argu- 
 ments of Mr. Disraeli in 1859 as being fatal to the
 
 202 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 anomalies of borough and county franchise created by 
 the Act of 1867. In introducing to the House of Com- 
 mons Lord Derby's Reform Bill of 1859, the young 
 Conservative leader defended the principle of a general 
 10 limit to the suffrage in these words " In order to 
 bring about a general content and sympathy between 
 the different parts of the constituent body, the govern- 
 ment proposes to recognize the principle of identity of 
 suffrage between counties and towns ". These words 
 now supplied reformers with an excellent text in their 
 new efforts for electoral reform. The claims of logic, 
 the sympathy of town artisans for their suburban or 
 rural brethren, the grievances which these suffered at the 
 hands of stupid vestries or harsh landlords, the need of 
 a completer representation of our ever-increasing manu- 
 facturing districts, all these topics furnished inexhaustible 
 materials for the champions of reform. The shortcom- 
 ings of the Redistribution Bill of 1867 were mercilessly 
 exposed. 1 It left one member apiece to 42 boroughs, 
 all of which had fewer than 7000 inhabitants; 142 
 boroughs, having a total population of 1,751,000, sent, 
 in all, 172 members to Westminster; while Liverpool, 
 Manchester, Birmingham, and Glasgow, containing 
 1,832,000 inhabitants, practically counted only 4 votes 
 in a parliamentary division. 
 
 But this was not, in the main, a question for the great 
 towns so much as for the rural districts. The climax 
 of the industrial revolution had been reached in the 
 years 1837-1848. The brunt of the agrarian crisis, 
 resulting from American competition and from other 
 causes which were explained in the last chapter, was felt 
 most keenly in and after the year 1876. Just as the 
 grinding pressure of want had at the earlier date en- 
 rolled hundreds of thousands of operatives in the Chartist 
 ranks, so now agricultural distress permeated farm 
 1 e.g. in Mr. John Noble's pamphlet on the Reform of Parliament.
 
 The Third Reform Act. 203 
 
 labourers, and for a time even farmers themselves, with 
 Radical notions. As has previously been shown, the 
 general election of 1880 was decided very largely by 
 agrarian questions. And when the severity of the agri- 
 cultural crisis was not appreciably mitigated by the 
 Ground Game Act, the abolition of the malt tax, and 
 other remedial measures, the plan of creating peasant 
 holdings gained general favour as affording a means of 
 solving the agricultural problem. If peasant proprietors 
 could not successfully meet American competition in 
 corn, yet in dairy and market - garden produce they 
 would surely be able to hold their own against the 
 peasants of France, Holland, and Denmark. At any 
 rate, the formation of peasant holdings would tend to 
 root the people in the soil, and stop the drift to the 
 towns which was depleting the country and crowding the 
 rookeries of London. Such were the ideas which were 
 soon to find definite expression in the idyllic programme 
 "three acres and a cow". Rural labourers themselves 
 were aroused from their usual lethargy, and looked on 
 the franchise as a means of attaining the felicity with 
 which Feargus O'Connor had enchanted the minds of 
 their fathers in the forties. It was evident that only 
 the Liberals or Radicals could now effect the transfor- 
 mation of rural Britain into the Arcadia of the poets; 
 for only this party could or would arm Hodge with the 
 modern diviner's wand, the franchise. 
 
 Such appear to have been the chief motives which 
 propelled onwards the democratic movement in and after 
 1880. Some there were who advocated household suf- 
 frage on the same lofty motives as those which animated 
 Joseph Sturge and the Complete- Suffrage party forty 
 years previously. Others again saw in a drastic elec- 
 toral change a means of ensuring the predominance of 
 domestic reforms over foreign affairs, and of recalling 
 the Liberal government from its Egyptian adventures,
 
 204 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Springing" from whatever motives, the demand of house- 
 hold suffrage for the counties gathered force and volume 
 through the years 1880-83, and it was skilfully enforced 
 by Liberal clubs. But the desire for electoral reform 
 was not by any means one-sided. The Conservative 
 party was no more opposed to a well-considered ex- 
 tension of the suffrage than it had been in the years 
 1859-1867. Conservative legislation had strengthened 
 the bonds connecting the party with town artisans; 
 and their party managers knew perfectly well that the 
 greater predominance which must be given to London, 
 to suburban districts, and to counties, would ultimately, 
 if not immediately, tell in their favour. Events have 
 fully justified their prescience. On the platform and in 
 the press there was some approach to unanimity as to 
 the need of a change. 1 The chief questions raised were 
 those relating to the method of procedure, though some 
 public men loudly questioned the desirability of effecting 
 an important transfer of political power in the midst of 
 the excitement aroused by Irish troubles and Egyptian 
 complications. 
 
 The last-named questions, however, furnished to the 
 rank and file of the Liberal party a reason for pushing 
 on electoral reform. The propelling power was certainly 
 exerted by Liberal clubs; and the whole movement 
 therefore presents a complete contrast to the course of 
 affairs in 1867, when the debates in the House first 
 aroused any general interest. Now the reverse was 
 signally the case. In pursuance of resolutions passed 
 
 1 "That there must be sooner or later a change in the electoral system 
 is admitted by all Liberals and almost all Conservatives; and it is hardly 
 possible for men of sense to avoid the conclusion that an early and final 
 settlement is from every point of view to be desired. If it be acknowledged 
 that the situation created by the Act of 1867 cannot be permanently main- 
 tained, it is clearly wise to remove at once an excuse for perpetual legislative 
 tinkering and to establish the relations of parties on a permanent basis. 
 The Conservative elements in English society will not be extinguished by 
 electoral changes " (Times, Oct. 16. 1883).
 
 The Third Reform Act. 205 
 
 by the National Liberal Federation in May, 1883, a great 
 meeting- of delegates of clubs was held at Leeds in 
 October to confer on the whole question. The first 
 resolution, urging the government to bring- in a Reform 
 Bill in the next session, was passed with enthusiasm, 
 an amendment moved by Mr. Firth in favour of giving 
 priority to London municipal reform being- negatived. 
 Speeches by Mr. Morley, Dr. Dale, and by that sturdy 
 veteran in the cause of reform, John Bright, made a 
 great impression. Those of Mr. Morley and Mr. Bright 
 are noteworthy as advising the separation of the ques- 
 tions of franchise and redistribution. The latter closed 
 with a threatening reference to the Lords in case they 
 resisted the change, or presumed to require the produc- 
 tion of the scheme of redistribution before the fate of the 
 Franchise Bill were decided. Mr. Morley, however, ad- 
 mitted that the Upper House had a "legitimate right", 
 if they chose to use it, of having the question of redis- 
 tribution submitted to the constituencies before accepting 
 the government plan. The precedent of 1866 could cer- 
 tainly be urged in favour of the claim, which was soon 
 to be urged by the Lords, that the whole scheme must 
 be made known before any decisive votes should have 
 been taken on the Franchise Bill. 
 
 We now proceed to notice the details of the Franchise 
 Bill, which Mr. Gladstone introduced into the House of 
 Commons on Feb. 5, 1884. He justified the action of 
 the government on grounds of justice and patriotism. 
 The strength of a modern state lay in its representative 
 institutions; and he claimed that the present proposals 
 would lay the foundations of government broad and 
 deep in the people's will, and would "array the people 
 in one solid compacted mass around the ancient throne 
 which it has loved so well, and round a constitution now 
 to be more than ever powerful and more than ever free". 
 The Act of 1832 had added considerably less than half
 
 206 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 a million of voters to the electorate; the immediate 
 results of the second Reform Act had been to extend 
 the suffrage by about 1,080,000; while the present bill 
 would enfranchise no fewer than 2,000,000. This would 
 be effected mainly by the extension of household suffrage, 
 and the lodger franchise of 1867, to counties and to 
 suburban districts previously merged in counties. But 
 in addition to the lodger vote of 1867 Mr. Gladstone 
 proposed to create a "service" franchise; that is, he 
 proposed to accord votes to officials, servants, grooms, 
 and the like, who occupied rooms or cottages, though 
 they paid no rent whatever. Turning to the question 
 of redistribution of seats, he justified its separation from 
 that of the franchise on the ground that it was infinitely 
 complex, sectional, and local, while the right of voting 
 should be determined on broadly national issues ; but he 
 expressed the "hope" that the more difficult question 
 might be settled in the following year. 
 
 In the debates which followed, Lord Randolph 
 Churchill objected to the bill as inopportune in a time 
 of foreign complications, and also on the more general 
 ground that agricultural labourers were, as a rule, quite 
 unfitted for the discharge of the same political rights 
 and duties as the far more intelligent manufacturing 
 and mining population. Mr. W. H. Smith opposed its 
 extension to Ireland, where it would lead to a policy of 
 confiscation of property. On the whole, however, the 
 opposition fastened on the separation of franchise and 
 redistribution as the most objectionable feature of the 
 scheme; and it would be puerile to deny that under 
 cover of this objection many members cloaked their 
 designs to thwart both proposals. Despite the almost 
 open threats to the Lords if they should resist or thwart 
 these propositions, the Upper House passed Lord Cairns' 
 amendment, which demanded the association with the 
 Franchise Bill of proposals for the redistribution of seats.
 
 The Third Reform Act. 207 
 
 At once there arose a furious hubbub. Charges and 
 countercharges hurtled through the air; and the sus- 
 picions thus aroused imported into our political life 
 unwonted heat and violence. It was in vain that Mr. 
 Gladstone proposed the passing of an identical resolu- 
 tion in each House that the Franchise Bill had been 
 or would be passed, in reliance on a promise of the 
 ministry to introduce a Redistribution Bill in the fol- 
 lowing session. That, exclaimed Lord Salisbury, offered 
 no guarantee that Mr. Gladstone would not introduce 
 a wholly objectionable scheme of redistribution, which 
 he might force down by aid of the Franchise Bill as 
 soon as it became law. " Show us all your plans, or 
 we will not pass the first instalment", exclaimed the 
 Peers and their Tory backers. "No," retorted the 
 Liberals in effect, "you want us to link both together 
 that you may defeat both. A two-legged race is not to 
 our fancy." So the conflict raged. The welkin of Mid- 
 lothian again re-echoed with oratory. Demonstrations, 
 threatening the ending or mending of the House of 
 Lords, darkened squares and market-places; pam- 
 phleteers and editors raked up the precedents of 1866 
 to prove anything and everything; the constitution tot- 
 tered. 
 
 But amidst all the racket the small voice of common 
 sense began to whisper of compromise. As has been 
 already shown, the two parties were by no means irre- 
 concilably opposed on the principle of the proposed 
 measures. Uncompromising divergence of aims char- 
 acterized only the intransigeants of each side, and the 
 tacticians who saw in the conflict a means of abolishing 
 the Upper House. But these feelings were confined to 
 a few. The passions of the moderate men on both sides 
 were hardly so inflamed as to defy the appeals of reason. 
 Their resentment had been aroused by the suspicion that 
 their opponents were working to outwit or overreach
 
 208 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 them. The occasion evidently called for the services of 
 two or three "honest brokers", and these now quietly 
 arranged the conditions for a conference of the leading 
 men on both sides. 1 When rhetoric yielded place to 
 reason the whole thing was found to be capable of ar- 
 rangement. The private conferences held between Mr. 
 Gladstone, Lord Hartington, and Sir Charles Dilke on 
 the one side, and Lord Salisbury and Sir Stafford North- 
 cote as leaders of the opposition, unravelled the parlia- 
 mentary tangle. The Upper House now agreed to pass 
 the Franchise Bill on its second reading, with the under- 
 standing that the forthcoming Redistribution Bill should 
 be made "the subject of friendly communications". 2 
 The committee stage of the Franchise Bill and its third 
 reading were postponed, in the House of Lords, until 
 the Redistribution of Seats Bill had been introduced by 
 Mr. Gladstone into the House of Commons. 
 
 The general principles of this second very important 
 measure were now explained by the premier. Without 
 adopting the scheme of equal electoral districts, the 
 Redistribution Bill aimed at bringing about approximate 
 equality of representation ; but there was to be little or no 
 abolition of historic names, such as had moved the fears 
 of the opposition. Towns containing fewer than 15,000 
 inhabitants were, for electoral purposes, to be merged in 
 the county districts to which in most cases they demised 
 their names. Towns where the population ranged 
 between 15,000 and 50,000 were to return one member 
 only. These changes liberated 160 seats, in addition to 
 which six seats, previously declared vacant for bribery, 
 
 1 In Mr. Andrew Lang's Life of Lord Iddesleigh, vol. ii. pp. 205-215, the 
 details will be found. First the Duke of Richmond, and, later, Lord 
 Norton, hinted at a meeting of the leaders. Lord Iddesleigh (then Sir 
 Stafford Northcote), in a secret interview with Mr. Gladstone at St. James's 
 Palace, helped to clear away misunderstandings. The separation of sub- 
 urban and rural districts was desired by both. Other difficulties, viz. those 
 of procedure, were also removed, and asperities were smoothed dow:>, 
 
 2 For details, see Hansard, Nov. 17, 18, 1884.
 
 The Third Reform Act. 209 
 
 were to ; be revived. These six were to go to England. 
 Scotland received an increase of twelve members, while 
 the number of members for Wales and Ireland remained 
 unchanged. As a result, the membership of the House 
 of Commons was raised from 658 to 670. Further, the 
 principle of single -member divisions was generally 
 adopted, 1 a decision which drew an unavailing protest 
 from the champions of proportional representation, Mr. 
 Courtney and Sir John Lubbock. In vain did they point 
 out that the minute subdivisions of towns and counties 
 would frequently distort the verdict of the town or 
 county as a whole. The single-member plan evidently 
 had the merit of being simpler, and therefore of being 
 more easily worked by a half-educated electorate, and 
 the cause to which John Stuart Mill had devoted his 
 energies was accordingly shelved, as in 1867. The 
 result is that the 670 members of Parliament are now 
 mostly elected in a multitude of small areas, where local 
 or parochial concerns frequently overshadow the larger 
 national questions which are presumed to be solely 
 under consideration. 
 
 Apart from this defect, which perhaps may be to some 
 extent remedied by the spread of education and growth 
 of intelligence, the Redistribution Bill may be regarded as 
 effecting an important and satisfactory change. For the 
 first time London and the new industrial centres received 
 their due share of political power, which hitherto had 
 been absorbed by petty townships of the south and east. 
 In place of 22 members, London and its vast suburban 
 districts were to return 62; and the numbers allotted 
 to the chief towns were as follows : Liverpool, 9 ; Man- 
 chester and Salford, 9; Glasgow, 7; Birmingham, 7; 
 Leeds, 5; Sheffield, 5; Edinburgh, Dublin, Belfast, and 
 Bristol, 4 each; and so on. Equally great were the 
 
 1 The exceptions were the City of London, and towns of from 50,000 to 
 165,000 inhabitants, which were to return two members apiece. 
 
 (M416) O
 
 210 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 gains to the manufacturing counties, Yorkshire return- 
 ing 26 members, and Lancashire 23, apart from those 
 sent up by their towns. Even so, the voting power of 
 London and the great towns of England is not relatively 
 so great as that of distant country districts, especially 
 those of Ireland. But, as was asserted by Mr. Gladstone, 
 the very remoteness and sparseness of population of 
 those districts constituted a claim for departing from a 
 strictly numerical basis. The great towns could well 
 look after themselves, because "the actual political 
 power in these concentrated masses is sharper, quicker, 
 and more vehement". 
 
 In many respects the Franchise Act of 1884 and the 
 Redistribution of Seats Act of 1885 are the most impor- 
 tant measures of the century. Their significance can 
 only be fully realized by the student who has traced the 
 course of the democratic movements of the previous 
 generations. Manhood suffrage and equal electoral dis- 
 tricts, two of the claims of Major Cartwright and his 
 reform committee of 1780, and, later, two of the points 
 of the original People's Charter, were now approximately 
 secured. The extension of prosperity to the poorer 
 classes has brought the position of holder of a tenement, 
 or of a lodger, within the reach of all who can by any 
 stretch of the imagination be regarded as capable of 
 the intelligent discharge of political duties. Indeed, 
 the experience of recent years would seem to show that 
 among the newly enfranchised classes the very poor give 
 a fitful and almost unreasoning adherence to either party, 
 and cause those swift and apparently unaccountable 
 vacillations which are the despair of responsible poli- 
 ticians and the joy of "wreckers". 
 
 While the approach to manhood suffrage has been as 
 close as any friends of political stability could wish, the 
 approximation to equal electoral districts has been less 
 pronounced. The desire to spare historic towns was
 
 The Third Reform Act. 211 
 
 prompted by a no less amiable feeling than that which 
 perpetuated old names and areas wherever possible. As 
 a result, the new county divisions may be regarded as a 
 far more satisfactory compromise between the old and 
 the new, between tradition and modern needs, than the 
 singularly uninteresting departmental divisions imposed 
 on France by the rigorously mathematical democrats of 
 1789. The different methods employed are characteristic 
 of French and English democracy. No less noteworthy 
 is the peaceful character of the transition to a new 
 electoral system, which forty years earlier had been 
 declared to be subversive of the constitution and of the 
 rights of property. This fact is another signal instance 
 of the adaptive powers of the English parliamentary 
 system. In 1848 it seemed as impossible that any House 
 of Commons should ever pass the substance of the 
 People's Charter as, in 1830, that the borough-mongers' 
 Parliament should pronounce sentence of death on Old 
 Sarum. Yet both agitations achieved an almost blood- 
 less triumph through the very Parliament which was 
 denounced as corrupt or imperfect. Never surely has 
 the wit of man devised any scheme which, while subject- 
 ing all proposals to salutary sifting and delay, has so 
 persistently left the door of hope ajar in view of the 
 multitude which sought admittance. If, as the critic of 
 democracy asserts, 1 satisfaction and impatience, "the 
 two great sources of political conduct", were reasonably 
 satisfied by our older electoral system, surely it may be 
 admitted that the Acts of 1884-85 gave a reasonably 
 tardy and cautiously incomplete gratification to the aims 
 and desires cherished by democrats for two or three 
 generations. 
 
 Limits of space preclude any attempt at a detailed 
 examination of the legislation which resulted more or 
 less directly from the Acts of 1884-85. Nor, indeed, has 
 1 Sir H. Maine's Popular Government.
 
 212 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 the time come when any such attempt can be essayed 
 with satisfactory results. The general election of 1885 
 showed how strong were the feelings of agricultural 
 labourers in favour of drastic agrarian reforms. While 
 Conservative triumphs in the boroughs were surprisingly 
 numerous, the voice of the two millions of enfranchised 
 voters was given with no uncertain sound for the policy 
 of small holdings. As a result, 334 Liberals, 250 Con- 
 servatives, and 86 Irish Home Rulers, came up to 
 Westminster; and the makeshift government of Lord 
 Salisbury was ejected by the adoption of an amendment 
 to the address expressing regret that there was no men- 
 tion of allotments for labourers (Jan. 1886). But a 
 surprise was in store. Mr. Gladstone, instead of basing 
 the existence of his new government on the agricultural 
 questions which had brought it to power, suddenly 
 executed a strategic right turn towards Mr. Parnell's 
 following. This action speedily ruptured the Liberal 
 party, and brought about a new grouping in the political 
 kaleidoscope. On the defeat of the first Home Rule 
 Bill, Mr. Gladstone appealed to the country, which 
 retorted by electing 316 Conservatives, 191 Liberal 
 Home Rulers, 78 Liberal Unionists, and 85 Irish Home 
 Rulers. The alliance between Conservatives and Liberal 
 Unionists, the latter led by Lord Hartington and Mr. 
 Chamberlain, has had the effect of completing the politi- 
 cal education of the Tory party, which Sir Robert Peel 
 and Mr. Disraeli had so strenuously commenced. 
 
 Opportunism, introduced by the Act of 1867, now 
 rushed in like a flood and began to obliterate the old 
 party landmarks. The democratic principle was for- 
 mally adopted by Lord Salisbury's government in its 
 very important Local Government Bill of 1888, which 
 introduced into counties and a few large boroughs (in- 
 cluding London) an electoral system based on household 
 suffrage. For the first time in our history since the
 
 The Third Reform Act. 213 
 
 decay of the old folk-moots, county affairs were placed 
 on a completely popular basis; and the government of 
 London regained the democratic character which it had 
 lost since the perversion of the mediaeval trade gilds 
 from their primitive uses. The Gladstone ministry in 
 1893 introduced a bill, which was passed in the following 
 year, extending the elective principle to rural parishes 
 having a population of 300 or more. All householders 
 were to have votes in the parish meeting, which was to 
 be summoned at least once a year. The parochial coun- 
 cillors, having been elected by ballot, were to discharge 
 nearly all the functions of the old vestry meeting a 
 stunted survival of the old Saxon hundred-moot. The 
 new council deals with sanitary affairs, can acquire land 
 for allotments or for recreation, and may under certain 
 conditions found a free library. It is, in fact, an adapta- 
 tion of the old democratic hundred-moot to the needs of 
 the present age. 
 
 A survey of the political history of this century seems 
 to prove that there is an irresistible tendency in the 
 English people to hark back to the earlier conditions of 
 the national life. Sometimes it is the result of a con- 
 scious adoption of an earlier programme, as when the 
 more intelligent Chartists justified their demands by 
 reference to those of 1780; while the reformers of 1780 
 had also appealed to the venerable charters of English 
 liberties. In those cases the recurrence to earlier pre- 
 cedents was deliberate and avowed. In other instances, 
 similar conduct has been the outcome of the unconscious 
 but imperious instincts of a sturdy stock, which in the 
 long run repels all the warping influences of Feudalism, 
 and reverts to the old Saxon ways. This is at once the 
 paradox and the salvation of English political life, that 
 even its innovating efforts tend to the conservation or 
 reconstruction of the old national and local institutions.
 
 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 Democracy and Labour. 
 
 Though it is impossible to review the whole area of 
 legislative activity since the inauguration of a new epoch 
 by the Acts of 1884-85, yet it seems desirable to examine 
 the bearing of the new developments on two very im- 
 portant spheres of our national life, labour legislation 
 and foreign policy. On the satisfaction of the very 
 diverse and often antagonistic demands which confront 
 the British government in industrial life and in foreign 
 relations, must chiefly depend the future of this people. 
 
 In attempting to review the course of recent industrial 
 legislation it will be well at the outset to examine the 
 question in the light of the events of 1830-1850. The 
 persistence of national character, and even the tenacity 
 with which working-men have clung to earlier aims and 
 methods, will probably furnish a clue as to the meaning 
 of present developments. What, then, were the aims 
 which inspired artisan leaders in the period just named? 
 Were those men communists and levellers ; or did they 
 seek practical means for the redress of definite griev- 
 ances? 
 
 It may be urged that Chartism was closely connected 
 with Robert Owen's propaganda and that of Hodgkin, 
 the former of whom expressly claimed for his scheme a 
 world-wide application ; also that several of the Chartists 
 retained to the end the regenerating and levelling theories 
 which they learnt from those thinkers. That statement 
 is only partly correct. Lovett, Hetherington, and a few 
 other moral-force Chartists were at first disciples of 
 Owen ; and the latter strongly avowed in his Poor Man's 
 Guardian that all distinctions of rank and property must 
 be swept away. The prime impulse which drove Lovett
 
 Democracy and Labour. 215 
 
 and Hetherington into Radicalism was undoubtedly the 
 teaching" of Owen and Hodgicin, which promised a speedy 
 and effectual cure for the prevalent misery. But before 
 the definite revival of the old democratic programme in 
 the People's Charter, these two able artisan leaders had 
 seen the error of their ways. Lovett broke away from 
 his teacher in order to found a co-operative society on 
 practical lines, and openly renounced the follies of 
 Owenism; 1 while Hetherington, on the decease of his 
 acrid print in 1835, found it desirable to commence 
 another which contained more news and fewer diatribes 
 against property. Many other proofs might be cited in 
 proof of the declining popularity of Owen's and Hodg- 
 kin's ideas about that time. 2 The introduction to the 
 People's Charter drawn up by Lovett, conveys no hint 
 that any redistribution of property was aimed at. The 
 first number of O'Connor's Northern Star, as we have 
 seen in chapter v., dangled before working--men the 
 prospect of equality with their richer neighbours and of 
 a "respectable provision" for "every unwilling idler in 
 the state ". But even this vaguely alluring- programme 
 was afterwards tacitly shelved, and the only practical 
 result was the very harmless Land Scheme, which may be 
 regarded as the precursor of "three acres and a cow". 
 The evidence points directly to the fact that the mass of 
 our people, even amidst the misery of the thirties and 
 forties, were ultimately repelled rather than attracted by 
 
 1 In Appendix I. to his able work The Labour Problem (1896) Mr. G. 
 Drage, M. P. , seems to me to assign too much importance to the supposed 
 levelling schemes of the early Chartists. In support of his views he quotes 
 a few phrases from the address sent by the London Working-men's Associa- 
 tion to Belgian artisans as to the producers of wealth having the first claim 
 to its enjoyment. But, as Lovett shows in his Autobiography, this was in 
 1836, and was called forth by special circumstances ; and on page 45 he 
 states why he gave up communism, though he clung to the co-operative 
 production of wealth. 
 
 8 See my article on "The Unstamped Press, 1815-36", in the English 
 Historical Review of October, 1897, which shows the small circulation of 
 Owenite and other " levelling" papers.
 
 216 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 the levelling theories advocated more or less openly by 
 Spence, Robert Owen, and Hodgkin. Enthusiasts like 
 Lovett, Hetherington, and Bronterre O'Brien, who at 
 first disseminated these notions, were gradually brought, 
 either by their own better sense or by that strange yet 
 almost unerring instinct which guides our people on 
 these subjects, to abandon them altogether, or to embody 
 them in practical demands, such as that for the due 
 taxation of wealth, which have finally been adopted by 
 responsible statesmen. 
 
 This fact is of the utmost importance. In a time of 
 the keenest distress, rendered additionally acute by the 
 Corn-law and the Poor-law, English artisans turned away 
 from the theorists who were demanding a reconstruction 
 of society and a redistribution of property, and threw 
 their weight almost wholly into a movement which aimed 
 first and foremost at effecting through Parliament a 
 remedy of their worst grievances. Well may Carlyle 
 praise John Bull because, "after infinite tumblings and 
 spoken platitudes innumerable from barrel-heads and 
 parliament-benches, he does settle down somewhere 
 about the just conclusion: you are certain that his 
 jumblings and tumblings will end, after years or cen- 
 turies, in stable equilibrium ". Truly so, to an extent of 
 which the seer of Chelsea could not have dreamed. No 
 other people has gone through such miseries, and these 
 too enhanced by law, and has listened to the siren voice 
 of confiscation, without heading straight for the rocks. 
 
 The bearing of this on existing political conditions is 
 fairly obvious. The people of the United States have been 
 declared to be the despair of extreme socialists. Their 
 individualism, their sense of what is due to individual 
 enterprise and liberty, whether during life or in the right 
 of bequest to posterity, is so keen that it throws off even 
 the most potent arguments drawn from the armoury of 
 Karl Marx. This is after all not surprising, consider-
 
 Democracy and Labour. 217 
 
 ing how pleasant are the places in which their lines are 
 cast, and how much of the total result is due to the 
 energy and ingenuity of individuals. But the marvel is 
 that in our old overcrowded country, where the landlords 
 lived at ease on broad domains while the many toiled 
 for a pittance in noisome townships and reeking- factories, 
 where the few made laws which pressed hard on the 
 many, yet there was no war of classes, no general rush 
 for division of land or distribution of wealth, but a 
 steady resolve to use the law to mend the law, and to 
 regain for the masses that grip on the People's House 
 which had been the bulwark of the nation's liberties. 
 
 But, while discarding the viewy schemes of Owen, 
 our artisans always regarded political rights as a means 
 of bettering their position by practical reforms. It was 
 natural that they should look on politics from this 
 practical stand-point. To gain a vote meant to regain 
 part at least of the creature comforts which had been 
 lost amid the shifting scenes of nineteenth-century life. 
 Time was when some of them had been well-to-do wool- 
 combers or hand-loom weavers ; l perchance their fathers 
 had been freeholders in the county, and had been courted 
 and bribed for their votes as assiduously as the stout 
 yeoman in the village election scene depicted by Hogarth. 
 At any rate, they had heard about the good old times 
 before the great war, when prices were cheap, work was 
 regular, and wages were good. Why, then, should 
 they, the sons, sink to the position of drudges without 
 rights and privileges, because fate had doomed them to 
 work in a township for a master who knew them not? 
 Such were the notions dimly hovering in the minds of 
 the wage-earners, impelling them to demand the fran- 
 
 1 " Lancashire was once a particularly loyal county. A call was made on 
 their patriotism to repel the gigantic power of Bonaparte: 30,000 volunteers 
 stepped forward, and upwards of 20,000 were hand-loom weavers. . . Dare 
 any government now call upon the services of such a people living upon 
 three shillings a week?" (Part. Report 0/1834).
 
 2t8 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 chise as a means of redressing the balance which the 
 statesman and the engineer had tilted against them. 
 
 Viewing the matter morally and historically, their action 
 was completely justifiable. The details presented in my 
 first chapter prove that the industrial and agricultural 
 changes which rendered the first half of this century for 
 ever memorable depressed the status of the poor even 
 while they enhanced the wealth of the community. On 
 the ground of justice and even of expediency the wage- 
 earners might accordingly claim every consideration 
 from the community in respect to all their worst griev- 
 ances. These were an oppressive taxation, unhealthy 
 conditions both in the cottage and the factory, inability 
 to gain compensation for injury incurred while in the 
 employer's service, and inadequate return for the long 
 hours of labour. It was for the redress of these practical 
 grievances that British artisans claimed the franchise, 
 and not for the establishment of an ideal society or for 
 the levelling of incomes. The close connection between 
 industrial wrongs and the growth of Chartism is every- 
 where obvious. Fed on the misery of 1837-42, the 
 movement declined after that date, except where bitter 
 and prolonged strikes went against the men. Reviving 
 in 1847-48 amidst the trade depression, lock-outs, and 
 reduction of wages of those years, it was lulled to rest 
 by the gold discoveries and commercial prosperity which 
 marked the next decade. 1 Workmen who had gained 
 their immediate needs, regular work and better wages, 
 could afford to wait for the future, which indeed has 
 brought far more than any of them ever conceived in the 
 important changes that we will now briefly examine. 
 
 It is a curious fact, but easily capable of proof, that 
 
 1 The evidence afforded by the Chartist Convention of 1848 on this point 
 is conclusive. Nearly all the speakers urged that the general misery com- 
 pelled a forward movement. Only the Edinburgh delegate said that his 
 constituents were not poverty-stricken Chartists, but " Chartists from prin- 
 ciple ". See Gammage, The Chartist Movement, p. 303 (edit of 1894).
 
 Democracy and Labour. 219 
 
 the first demand for interference between the employer 
 and employed came from philanthropists and benevolent 
 employers, not from the workmen themselves. The 
 earliest Factory Acts, those of 1802 and 1819, were the 
 result of representations made by local authorities and 
 by enlightened masters, among whom were the first 
 Sir Robert Peel and Robert Owen, as to the miserable 
 state of the children and young people employed in many 
 factories. Of all Robert Owen's actions none was more 
 beneficent than his endeavour by legislation to extend to 
 all factories some of the benefits which he freely accorded 
 to his work-people at New Lanark. Though meeting with 
 only limited success, his example stimulated the action of 
 others, even though they totally disagreed with the other 
 features of his political and social creed. Lord Ashley 
 (afterwards Lord Shaftesbury), and Messrs. Sadler, Oast- 
 ler, and Stephens, were the next champions of the 
 factory hands. All four were Tories of the old school, 
 resolute opponents of Whig manufacturers and laisser- 
 faire economists; and their efforts, aided by those of 
 Mr. Fielden, a man who had raised himself from the 
 ranks to be a wealthy manufacturer and Radical member 
 for Oldham, were chiefly instrumental in gaining the 
 Acts of 1833, 1844, and 1847. The last of these, limit- 
 ing the work of all young persons and women to 10 hours 
 a day and 58 a week, crowned with success the efforts 
 of influential men who for nearly twenty years had 
 chivalrously been pleading the cause of the weak and 
 helpless. The arguments of Lord Ashley and his coad- 
 jutors were based mainly on moral grounds, though they 
 were careful to show that previous reductions of the hours 
 of labour, while raising the quality of the work, had not 
 sensibly diminished the output. 1 The Ten Hours Act, 
 together with the Mines Act of 1842, marks the close of 
 
 iSee Lord Shaftesbury's speeches in House of Commons, March 15, 
 May 10, 1844, and January 29, 1846, in his volume of Speeches (1868).
 
 220 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 what may be termed patriarchal legislation on this sub- 
 ject. Other acts, it is true, especially those resulting 
 from the royal commission of 1862-66, for which Lord 
 Shaftesbury had moved, extended the area of state pro- 
 tection to women and to young persons working in 
 workshops. But the working of Tory Socialism received 
 its most striking illustration in the earlier Acts, which 
 were so largely due to the untiring energy and noble 
 zeal of Lord Shaftesbury. 
 
 The evidence adduced by him before the royal com- 
 missions of inquiry seems to have aroused the attention 
 of working-men to the advantages which they themselves 
 might procure through the reduction of the hours of 
 labour of women and young persons ; and the conviction 
 spread that legislation might and must be attempted for 
 men. This notion, all but dormant before 1837, was 
 vitalized by the misery of the following years, when the 
 labour question leapt to life in something resembling its 
 present form. Strikes there had been, of course, before 
 1837, but none so well organized or so desperately fought 
 as those of 1842 and 1843 in the textile, iron, and coal 
 industries. For the present, most of the workers re- 
 venged themselves for defeat by supporting the Chartists; 
 but their prudent members began to turn their attention 
 more to labour questions than to an ultra -democratic 
 franchise. For, after all, what was the value of a vote 
 to most of them except to redress their most crying 
 grievances? And if other means would work as effectu- 
 ally and far more speedily, why not adopt them rather 
 than the "six points"? Why not try Trade-unionism 
 rather than Chartism? The former movement brought 
 a direct pressure to bear on the employer; while the 
 latter staked all on the attainment of the points as a 
 prelude to parliamentary interference. If many of their 
 best friends looked askance at the Charter, obviously it 
 was the best policy to drop the parliamentary question
 
 Democracy and Labour. 221 
 
 for the time and trust to those instincts of self-help which 
 are fortunately so strong" in the breast of every Briton. 
 As the capture of the strikes of 1842-43 by the physical- 
 force Chartists had done harm both to Trade-unionism 
 and to Chartism, surely it was better for Trade-unionists 
 to leave the points to shift for themselves and to look 
 after the sufficiently complex interests of the several 
 trades. Such were the motives which after 1843 tended 
 to separate the labour questions of the time from the dis- 
 tinctively parliamentary programme of the ultra-Radicals. 
 After the temporary collapse of the latter in 1848 the 
 self-help movement, whether trade-unionist or co-opera- 
 tive, received valued help from the advocacy of King-sley, 
 Maurice, and other far-seeing friends of the working- 
 classes, and ceased, for the time at least, to have any 
 close connection with the franchise question. This, 
 apparently, was one reason why the Chartist and Radical 
 cause remained all but stationary in the ensuing- years, 
 until the fervour of a few statesmen and the intrigues of 
 parties placed within reach of town artisans the weapon 
 of household suffrage for which they had vainly struggled 
 in the "forties". 
 
 It is now fairly clear that the granting- of this impor- 
 tant political right by Disraeli's Act of 1867 decided the 
 whole future of Trade-unionism. The year 1867 was 
 indeed a critical one. Public opinion was deeply incensed 
 by the trade-union outrages at Sheffield. Men listened 
 only to the sordid details of bullying", rattening 1 , explosion 
 and murder, forgetting- that these acts were largely due 
 to the laws which banned Trade-unionism and allowed 
 prejudiced judges to class as conspiracy all attempts 
 peacefully to persuade workmen to a strike. Fortunately 
 for all parties the searching- parliamentary inquiry, which 
 was held in 1867-69, revealed not only the sensational 
 details of outrage, but the leg-alized injustice under which 
 workmen in many of the cutlery trades suffered. It
 
 222 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 condemned the law as well as the law-breaker. Further- 
 more, it showed that what Hallamshire needed was not 
 less but more Trade-unionism. Outrages had been 
 most rife in the trades which, for various reasons, had 
 not been able fully to organize themselves. Completer 
 organization was proved to have been accompanied by 
 diminution of the use of brute force. Combination of 
 the workers in legal trade-unions was therefore presum- 
 ably a means of substituting more peaceful methods for 
 the dastardly acts by which small groups of desperate 
 men thought to better their position. Such a combina- 
 tion would at least provide a recognized channel for 
 negotiations between masters and men in case of dispute. 
 
 The inquiry would certainly not have been so favour- 
 able to the workers had they not recently been en- 
 franchised. As their votes were now of vast importance, 
 it was evidently desirable to conciliate them. The change 
 in the tenor of the inquiry between 1867 and 1869 suffi- 
 ciently shows that not only conviction as to the justice 
 of the claims of labour, but the desire to catch the 
 labour vote, played a part in the deliberations at West- 
 minster. Beginning with a general conviction of the need 
 of repressive legislation, the inquiry ended with recom- 
 mendations generally favourable to Trade-unionism. 1 
 
 This soothing policy led to a marked change in labour 
 questions. As Parliament now held the stirrup, it only 
 remained for Trade-unionism lightly to vault into the 
 saddle. One or two preliminary steps were alone 
 necessary. The first was to form an annual Trade- 
 union Congress, as was done in 1868. The next was 
 to form the parliamentary committee of the Trade-union 
 Congress, which is elected on the last day of the congress 
 for the purpose of influencing labour legislation. The 
 fruits of this activity were soon obvious. In 1871 came 
 the act which gave to trade-unions a definite legal status 
 i Schulze-Gaevernitz, Social Peace, p. 97.
 
 Democracy and Labour. 223 
 
 such as they had never previously enjoyed, and enabled 
 them to prosecute fraudulent officials. Four years later, 
 under a Conservative ministry, the law was modified in 
 a sense even more favourable to trade-unionists. The 
 Conspiracy and Protection of Property Act withdrew 
 trade-unions from the class of suspected organizations, 
 and conceded to them the right of using all peaceful 
 means of persuasion even at the time of a strike. Indeed, 
 a prominent champion of the cause admitted that the 
 two statutes of 1871 and 1875 "constituted a great and 
 generous measure of justice which none of us expected". 1 
 As a result, Trade-unionism soon lost the violence which 
 goes hand in hand with illegality, and which therefore 
 characterizes the cognate movement on the Continent. 
 Nothing is more gratifying than the orderly and law- 
 abiding spirit generally characteristic of English trade- 
 union delegates, as contrasted with the anarchic out- 
 bursts of their continental brethren. 
 
 But while English Trade-unionism has been law-abid- 
 ing, it has also been exceedingly active in moulding the 
 law to its will. Some little time elapsed before the 
 mass of workmen realized the full extent of the powers 
 freely conceded to them by Parliament; but after grasp- 
 ing the facts of the situation, they have struggled for 
 and obtained privileges which their forefathers would 
 have deemed impossible. The way had also been pre- 
 pared for them in 1864 and 1867 by factory legislation 
 limiting the hours of labour for women and young per- 
 sons to fifty-six per week. This restriction of time for 
 women and young persons naturally aided the men in 
 their endeavours to gain a similar boon ; and as a matter 
 of fact, before the year 1880 in most industries the men's 
 hours were fewer than the legal maximum for women. 
 
 Previous to the year 1889 there was little if any de- 
 
 iMr. H. Crompton: quoted in Appendix C of Howell's Handy Book of 
 the Labour Laws (1876).
 
 224 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 mand for universal legislation on the subject of hours of 
 work. The cry for an eight -hours day for all trades 
 constitutes a new and very significant departure. Par- 
 liament, it is true, had legislated for children, young 
 persons, and for women, working in factories and work- 
 shops. But factory legislation for adult males was a 
 very different matter, especially after 1867, when they 
 had votes and were organized in powerful unions. The 
 men of grit and independence who had fought the battles 
 of Trade-unionism in the past protested against whole- 
 sale parliamentary interference on complex questions 
 which had hitherto been decided between the masters 
 and the trade-unions themselves. Such complete re- 
 liance on Parliament would, they maintained, cut the 
 ground from under Trade-unionism; for what was the 
 need of the unions, if their knowledge of the complex 
 and shifting requirements of the several trades was 
 all to be set aside in favour of an arbitrary code framed 
 at Westminster? The demand for an eight-hours day 
 by the fiat of Parliament might possibly be successful 
 in the long run; but it would imply the abdication of 
 Trade-unionism in favour of a State Socialism of the 
 most rigid description. 
 
 In spite of these warnings the cry for a universal 
 Eight Hours Bill grew in intensity and volume. It 
 seems to have been powerfully influenced by a remark- 
 able Socialist propaganda undertaken by the Fabian 
 Society in and after 1886. That society, then abandon- 
 ing the cautious methods which its name seemed to 
 imply, entered the arena of party politics. Under the 
 generalship of Mr. Sidney Webb, 1 the Fabians girded 
 themselves for the conflict by forming a parliamentary 
 committee somewhat on the same lines as that of the 
 Trade-union Congress. The duties of this new body 
 were "to organize Socialist opinion, and to bring pres- 
 1 Fabian Tract, No. 41.
 
 Democracy and Labour. 225 
 
 sure to bear upon Parliament, municipalities, and other 
 representative bodies". Labour legislation of a more 
 drastic type than trade-unionists had hitherto favoured, 
 occupied a prominent place in the new propaganda; and 
 there can be no doubt that the demand for an eight- 
 hours day was largely due to the vigorous agitation 
 thus inaugurated. The Labour movement speedily felt 
 the effect of the new agitation and assumed the militant 
 form known as the New Unionism. Among the many 
 topics which separate it from the older trade organiza- 
 tions the most prominent is reliance on state control, 
 which, as we have seen, had previously been viewed 
 with distrust or dislike. It is questionable whether the 
 new movement would have secured much support but 
 for the worldly wisdom which associated it with the 
 alluring programme of a universal eight- hours day. 
 Not that this was mooted in its entirety at the outset. 
 At first it was proposed for all men employed by govern- 
 ment, by municipalities, and by other governing bodies. 
 Next it was held out to miners, and secured the adhesion 
 of the newly- formed National Federation of Miners. 
 Finally, the proposal was brought up at the Trade-union 
 Congress of 1890, in the following decisive form: that 
 "steps should be taken to reduce the working hours 
 in all trades to eight hours per day, or a maximum of 
 forty-eight per week; and while recognizing the power 
 and influence of trade organizations, it is of opinion that 
 the speediest and best method to obtain this reduction 
 for the workers generally is by parliamentary enact- 
 ment ". This wholesale regimentation of trades by Par- 
 liament was opposed by the delegate of the Durham 
 miners, who moved that the "eight-hours day should 
 be secured at once by such trades as may desire it"; 
 but the champions of universal legislation carried the 
 day by a majority of 8 in a meeting of 354 delegates. 1 
 
 1 Howell's Trade Unionism, New and Old, p. 174. 
 (H416) F
 
 226 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Not satisfied with throwing down the gauntlet, the 
 challenge became more sweeping and stringent. In its 
 extreme form, the proposal is that in every trade and 
 district, work shall in no case exceed eight hours a day, 
 or a total of forty-eight a week, overtime and extra pay 
 being entirely prohibited. The fortunes of this pro- 
 gramme have been instructive. The first efforts to 
 reduce it to practice were made by the industry which 
 claims the utmost consideration and sympathy. If any 
 calling demands close and careful regulation by the State 
 it is that which involves the discomfort and risk, the 
 strain on muscle and brain, imposed on hewers of coal. 
 Accordingly, an Eight Hours Bill was drafted on behalf 
 of the colliers for 1892, when it was found that out of 
 the five miners' representatives in the House of Com- 
 mons three refused to support it. The reasons for this 
 refusal are to be found in the sturdy independence of 
 the Northumberland and Durham miners, who, having 
 by their own associations and indomitable energy im- 
 measurably improved their position, were not desirous 
 of outside control. Their experience of the working of 
 the well-meant Coal Mines Regulation Act of 1887 was 
 not wholly favourable. As has recently been proved by 
 the evidence forthcoming at the Labour Commission, they 
 found the limitation of the hours of work for boys pro- 
 duced a scarcity of boys, which hampered the work of the 
 highly-paid hewers. When the majority of men in one 
 of the most important coal-fields rejected further govern- 
 ment interference, it was only natural that the House of 
 Commons should reject the Eight Hours Bill of 1892, 
 as it did by a decisive majority of 112. The opposition 
 of the Tynesiders has accordingly retarded the accept- 
 ance of a universal Eight Hours Bill, even by the indus- 
 try which seemed most to require it. 
 
 Into the balance of evidence for and against the 
 general proposal for an eight-hours day it is impossible
 
 Democracy and Labour. 227 
 
 here to enter. 1 It is noteworthy, however, that the action 
 of the miners themselves has tended to check the con- 
 clusions somewhat hastily recorded at the Trade-union 
 Congresses of 1890-1892; and the sifting- process, which 
 forms a needful stage in every movement, was carried 
 still further in the inquiry held by the Parliamentary 
 Labour Commission of 1892-1894. The advantage of 
 cross-examination over rhetoric has never been more 
 strikingly illustrated than in the gradual weakening- of 
 the case for a universal Eight Hours Bill when sifted by 
 the royal commission. The inquiry revealed not only 
 the complexity of the problem, but the opposing- nature 
 of the claims urg-ed on its behalf. Those who desired 
 to raise wages stated that the change would not check 
 production, and consequently would not absorb the 
 unemployed ; while those who benevolently desired to 
 absorb the unemployed into the ranks of regular workers 
 claimed that an eight-hours day would not increase the 
 cost of production. Here, then, the question stands for 
 the present. 
 
 One further result of the inquiry may also be noted. 
 Such enthusiastic champions of collectivism as Mr. 
 Sidney Webb and Mr. Tom Mann have implicitly, if not 
 explicitly, conceded the impracticability of a wholesale 
 regimentation of industry by national law. In his 
 evidence given before the Commission, Mr. Mann ad- 
 mitted that it would be advisable that exemptions be 
 granted when claimed by a local council composed of 
 employers and workmen, and that a three-fifths majority 
 of the adult workers in a trade should be necessary to 
 set in motion the local administrative machinery charge- 
 able with the working of the measure. Mr. Sidney Webb 
 
 1 See Labour Commission of 1892-94, fifth report ; also Mr. Drage's The 
 Labour Problem, pp. 94-129, Mr. Rae's Eight Hours for Work, Mr. S. 
 Webb's The Eight -Hours Day, Mr. Speyer's The Labour Commission 
 (1894), and Eight Hours by Law (Fabian Tract, No. 48). In the last, a 
 compromise called Trade Inquiry is recommended.
 
 228 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 also conceded the principle of local option for the smaller 
 industries, but asserted the need of general legislation 
 for the hours of labour in the staple industries of the 
 land, and of its execution by a department of the state. 
 
 The general impression produced by the evidence 
 before the Labour Commission would seem to be that the 
 interests and customs of localities, and even of different 
 sections of the same industry, are too diverse to be ruled 
 into line by a universal Eight Hours Bill. Many of the 
 delegates of trade-unions who spoke in its favour evi- 
 dently regarded it with apprehension in view of the 
 severity of foreign competition, though others took the 
 bull by the horns, and declared that the quality of work 
 would be so much improved by knocking off an hour, or 
 half an hour, as to afford the best, indeed the only, means 
 of meeting foreign competition. Few persons would 
 now deny that the reduction of the excessively long 
 hours of work of the previous generation has improved 
 the quality of work without reducing its quantity. The 
 same may be granted with respect to the abolition of 
 work before breakfast in some industries where the 
 strain on brain and muscle is very great, and in cases 
 where operatives have worked loyally and heartily under 
 the new conditions. But it does not follow that an 
 Eight Hours Bill would enable us to meet foreign 
 competition. German masters, who closely watch our 
 industrial affairs, show no great desire to shorten the 
 hours of work, as they would assuredly have done if 
 the argument as to the improved efficiency produced by 
 short hours were completely sound and generally appli- 
 cable. It would certainly be gratifying if the results of 
 recent reductions of hours in our land were so uniformly 
 favourable as to induce our continental rivals to curtail 
 the length of their working day in the hope of compass- 
 ing the ruin of England! 
 
 The value of a searching investigation by means of a
 
 Democracy and Labour. 229 
 
 royal commission has rarely been more illustrated than 
 in the question before us. The tendency of the new 
 electorate, now that it has fully grasped the extent of 
 its powers, is very naturally to call for wholesale 
 remedies, in the fond belief that they will speedily pro- 
 duce the results aimed at. Not until twenty years had 
 elapsed from the granting of household suffrage was 
 any distinctly able and energetic move made towards 
 the realization of State Socialism. After 1887 the move 
 developed almost into a rush. Trade-unionism of the 
 old well-established type, which accepted the wage- 
 system as a final fact, capable of being modified only by 
 the combined action of workers in the several industries, 
 was threatened with deposition by the so-called New 
 Unionism. This latter-day development was the off- 
 spring of the discontent created by the industrial stagna- 
 tion of the eighties and of the new school of practical 
 Socialism above referred to. It aimed at the capture of 
 existing unions, or the formation of new unions, the 
 latter to be merely "fighting machines", unencumbered 
 by the provident clubs to which the older unionists had 
 attached much importance. But the new unions were to 
 be more than industrial fighting machines : they were to 
 aid in the capture of Parliament and of projected local 
 assemblies by labour representatives, who should exploit 
 capitalistic industry in the interest of the workers. The 
 socialistic aims of the more advanced labour leaders were 
 set forth in the programme of the Independent Labour 
 Party, which was formed in January, 1892. Despite its 
 colourless title, the party put forward claims to "the 
 collective ownership and control of the means of produc- 
 tion, distribution, and exchange". Mr. Keir Hardie was 
 the only successful candidate for parliamentary honours 
 who went to the poll on this programme in 1892; and 
 in 1895 he failed to hold his seat. At the last general 
 election thirty Independent Labour candidates failed to
 
 230 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 capture a single seat among them ; l but they find 
 some consolation in the fact that 12*1 per cent of the 
 electors in those constituencies voted for the socialist 
 ticket. 
 
 Hitherto this programme has gained only a meagre 
 success. The reasons for the check suffered by it after 
 the first triumphs of 1889-1892 are not easy to assign. 
 The following suggestions are offered tentatively as 
 explaining some at least of the tendencies of recent social 
 and political developments. In the first place, it must 
 be observed that the New Unionism had prospered on 
 the discontent which inevitably accompanies stagnation 
 of trade. Weary of uncertainty of employment and 
 threatened reductions of wages, men naturally grasped 
 at the new forward policy ; and in the case of the famous 
 strike of the London dockers for their "tanner" a day 
 extra, and of the colliers in 1893, the new fighting policy 
 gained a striking success. But the terrible sufferings en- 
 dured by the colliers in the effort to prevent a temporary 
 reduction naturally tended to sober the victors, and 
 therefore to bring the New Unionism more into line with 
 the older trade organizations. Moreover, the very 
 aggressiveness of the new movement had tended to 
 magnify its difficulties by compelling masters to unite 
 and federate in self-defence. Instead of attacking single 
 masters, it was now confronted with powerful federations 
 of masters, who could weather the storms of a crisis or 
 endure the even more trying torpor of depression by the 
 aid of resources which neither the old unions nor the 
 new could hope to rival. 2 Besides, had not the old 
 
 1 Mr. John Burns, M.P. for Battersea, is not included in this number. 
 
 2 As Mr. Mallock has shown in his Labour and the Popular Welfare, bk. 
 iv. chapter 4, the power of the employer to resist a trade-union increases 
 in proportion as the demands of the latter trench more closely on the 
 margin of profit. The amount of trade-union funds decreased by 237,545 
 in the year 1893, mainly owing to the great coal strike. See Mr. Brabrook's 
 "Progress of Friendly Societies in 1884-1894", in Statistical Society 's Journal 
 of 1895.
 
 Democracy and Labour. 231 
 
 unions enormously improved the conditions of their 
 members by steady insistence and dexterous bargain- 
 ing-; and would it not be better to follow more in their 
 steps than to pursue a policy which would deplete their 
 own funds and array capital in a solid phalanx against 
 them? 
 
 Among other causes tending to give pause to the New 
 Unionism must also be reckoned the increasing efficacy 
 of self-help organizations, whether working in connec- 
 tion with, or on lines parallel to, the older trade-unions. 
 Self-help was again slowly but surely reasserting its 
 former influence over our wage-earning classes, as was 
 shown by official statistics. It is true that the Liberator 
 crash had seriously affected the position of building 
 societies ; but despite that terrible blow to the cause of 
 self-help, the funds of savings-banks, friendly societies, 
 &c., showed in 1894 a net increase of ^60,008,834 over 
 those of the year I884. 1 If progress so substantial had 
 been made in a decade remarkable for agricultural and 
 industrial depression, what might not be effected under 
 ordinarily favourable conditions, provided that the claims 
 of ability and capital on the one side, and, on the other, 
 the demands of labourers for the requisites of a decent 
 existence, were mutually recognized? 
 
 Then, again, the labour programme of the new Fabians 
 had to face the disadvantages which must ever attend 
 the manipulation of party politics. It is true that the 
 efforts put forward by the new labour party in 1890 had 
 a considerable effect on the Radical programme, which 
 Mr. John Morley put forward at Newcastle in Oct. 1891. 
 An increase of the powers of the new London County 
 Council, and the institution of district and parish councils, 
 formed two planks of the so-called Newcastle programme. 
 / For a time it secured the adhesion of most Liberals ; 
 and as this enthusiasm for Hodge was fanned by the 
 1 Mr. Brabrook's paper just quoted.
 
 232 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 excitement attending- the overthrow of a Conservative 
 government, all went merrily, until Liberals realized 
 that their Socialist allies regarded the new parochial 
 councils as machines to be worked by collectivist steam. 
 Then there was trepidation in the Liberal ranks, already 
 discontented because the "old gang" as Mr. Labouchere 
 irreverently termed it had absorbed most of the govern- 
 mental prizes. In vain did the collectivists demand the 
 municipalization of this and the parochialization of that. 
 The spirit of the Manchester school was raised to warn 
 off the new and dangerous allies, and to leave the Glad- 
 stone ministry free to devote all its energies to Home 
 Rule. 
 
 The sequel is only too well known. The ministry, 
 desirous of rousing the people for Home Rule and 
 against the House of Lords, went to the country; and 
 the country, by a vast majority, overthrew the Liberal 
 Home Rule government. Since the general election of 
 1895 Liberals, Irish Nationalists, and Socialists have 
 engaged in an interesting triangular duel, each party 
 blaming the other two for the disaster, and declaring 
 that, if its nostrum had been more to the front, things 
 would have gone very differently. The Socialists stoutly 
 affirm that had the Liberals carried through the collec- 
 tivist programme, with which they dallied for election- 
 eering purposes three years before, they might still hold 
 the reins of power ; but, as it is, their ' ' Manchesterism 
 has reduced them to this present pass". 1 As a Parthian 
 shaft deftly sped into the uncovered flank of a former 
 ally, the argument tells with effect. But the Liberal 
 legionary may turn aside the bolt by reminding the 
 Parthian irregular that the local elective councils, even 
 the London County Council itself, were generally 
 swamped by reactionaries ; whence it would appear that 
 collectivism has no more abiding charms when coaxingly 
 1 G. Bernard Shaw in Politics in 1896, p. 97.
 
 Democracy and Labour. 233 
 
 offered in municipal or parochial doses than when con- 
 fidently prescribed as a national recipe. 
 
 For the present, then, it would seem that John Bull 
 has elected to stand by old methods of tentative reform, 
 and refuses to exchange his old dwelling-place, so long- 
 as he can patch and extend it at will, for any commun- 
 istic phalanstere. The decision is what might be expected 
 from his eminently practical, respectable, and conven- 
 tional personality. As our whole inquiry has shown, 
 the typical Englishman dislikes to leap in the dark, and 
 only does so at the urgent invitation of party leaders 
 whom he thinks to be sound men. On the whole, he 
 much prefers to step cautiously, to hobble along rather 
 than to leap. Such methods do not lend themselves to 
 sensational incidents; but they serve to build up a 
 homely, if rather lumbering, political structure. These 
 characteristics have led him to ponder over and sift the 
 new and attractive programme put forward by able 
 young leaders, and select from it only the more practic- 
 able proposals, relegating even these to his old industrial 
 organizations for adoption or rejection as each may 
 decide. Never was there such exasperating eclecticism ! 
 Well may it move the bile of adroit compilers of pro- 
 grammes. 1 
 
 Meanwhile the interacting influence of democracy and 
 the labour movement has served to bring about a strange 
 reconstruction of parties. Cutting athwart the old party 
 lines, it has necessitated strategic wheelings and move- 
 ments to the rear, until the descendants of pre-reform 
 Toryism find themselves, not without many searchings 
 of heart, almost shoulder to shoulder with men who 
 once waved the red flag of revolutionary Socialism. 
 The party manceuvrings which led up to this result have 
 been described in previous chapters. Disraeli's Reform 
 Bill of 1867 gave decent burial to Toryism of the Lord 
 1 See Politics in 1896, p. 86.
 
 234 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Eldon type, and necessitated the adoption of a forward 
 policy of social reform and imperialism, on the due co- 
 ordination of which rest the fortunes of the whole British 
 race. 
 
 While this adroit leader was educating his party 
 for the future, the Liberals remained wedded to the 
 strongly individualist doctrines of the Manchester school, 
 to which Socialists have always been more opposed than 
 to the old Toryism. The way was therefore open for 
 something like a rapprochement between the younger 
 labour leaders and the more advanced Conservatives, 
 such as Lord Randolph Churchill. The enthronement 
 of democracy by the Liberal Reform Bills of 1884-85 
 tended to draw the extremes nearer together; for it 
 inaugurated a period of sheer opportunism, in which 
 each party strives to outbid the other in satisfying the 
 practicable claims of labour. Thus we see the strange 
 sight of a Conservative ministry pressing on a drastic 
 Employers' Liability Bill, despite the plaintive groans 
 of the ever-exploited Plugson, who imagined himself 
 safe at least for the life of one parliament. And while 
 a Unionist ministry is again at work "dishing the 
 Whigs ", the modern Socialist applauds the process. 
 For he too has changed. He no longer wears the 
 bonnet rouge: he has donned the silk hat. Under the 
 lead of the Fabians, he has developed a keen sense of 
 the superiority of parliamentary action to conspiracy and 
 barricades. He therefore no longer conspires against 
 Parliament, but strives to take it in tow. Still less does 
 he wage unrelenting war on the capitalist ; he exploits 
 the exploiter. He does not kill the goose that lays the 
 golden egg that was the mistake of his French brethren 
 in 1848 and 1871. His aim now is rather to submit her 
 to a strict and salutary regimen, and to municipalize 
 the eggs, leaving behind just enough to encourage the 
 creature.
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 235 
 
 Chapter XV. 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 
 
 To the most casual observer it must be obvious, if he 
 be not blinded by fanaticism, that neither on the Conti- 
 nent nor in the British Isles has democracy accomplished 
 the sweeping 1 changes in government which were antici- 
 pated by its warmest friends and bitterest foes in the 
 earlier or revolutionary phases. Some of the political 
 influences tending to retard its progress and moderate 
 its ardour have been noticed in previous chapters of 
 this little work. But there are others, having a wider 
 effect than any yet noted, that possibly are even more 
 potent than the mania for athleticism which absorbs 
 energies that would previously have been devoted to 
 politics. The most serious check to democracy has 
 undoubtedly been the embittering of national rivalries, 
 and consequent complications in foreign policy, such as 
 no popularly-elected Chamber can possibly unravel. 
 
 Were it possible to review the course of events on the 
 Continent, even a brief inquiry would probably suffice 
 to prove the connection between national jealousies and 
 that revival of autocracy which is so conspicuous a 
 feature of the present age. A slight acquaintance with 
 the course of recent continental politics will show that 
 the potent force of nationality, which Mazzini believed to 
 be essentially democratic, has strengthened the thrones 
 of the rulers of Prussia and Italy, and more recently 
 of Russia, who became its champions. The machinery 
 of diplomacy and the discipline of the royal armies 
 achieved the task which had defied the efforts of the 
 peoples themselves. Nationality could only effect the 
 unity of the German and Italian peoples by the aid of
 
 236 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 state-craft; and since the triumphs of 1870, democracy 
 has had to accept the compromise imposed by success- 
 ful statesmen and rulers. King William of Prussia and 
 Victor Emmanuel of Italy, along- with their shrewd 
 advisers, may therefore be regarded as the authors of 
 that mixed form of government which admits the people 
 to a considerable share in the legislative functions, but 
 reserves questions of foreign policy and national defence 
 almost exclusively to the control of the ruler and his 
 ministers. 
 
 Now, it is clear that when a state, wielding powers so 
 immense as those of Germany, adopts a mixed form of 
 government, which is scarcely more democratic than that 
 of the first Napoleon, an immense influence must be ex- 
 erted on the polity of neighbouring states. The effect of 
 militant autocracy on the fortunes of Western Europe 
 has also been vastly enhanced by the pressure of the 
 Eastern colossus. The predominance of Russia in 
 European affairs even threatens to renew, though in a 
 more guarded form, the Holy Alliance of the Eastern 
 potentates, who assiduously endeavoured to put back 
 the hands of the clock, not only in their own lands, but 
 throughout the whole of the Continent. France, once 
 the birthplace of new ideas, by her hostility to Germany, 
 and her desire to gain Russia's effective help, is now 
 reduced to a humiliating subservience to the wishes of 
 St. Petersburg ; and annoyance at the French occupation 
 of Tunis keeps the land of Mazzini and Garibaldi in 
 close alliance with the two central empires. It is the old 
 story. The jealousy of the peoples perpetuates methods 
 of autocratic rule which the progressives of 1848 and 
 1860 believed to have for ever passed away. 
 
 The experience of the past gives some cause for doubt- 
 ing whether popular government can be much more than 
 a name under the burdens imposed by a rigorous mili- 
 tarism and the checks administered by secret diplomacy.
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 237 
 
 Vast armaments imply not only a crushing- expenditure, 
 but also methods of administration which are incompatible 
 with free discussion and perpetual supervision by the 
 people's representatives. Even in time of peace armies 
 and navies must be controlled by a small number of 
 highly-trained experts; and in general the efficacy of 
 warlike preparations may be measured by the secrecy 
 with which they are carried out by almost irresponsible 
 officials, who can immediately dispose of great sums of 
 money. Now, every one of these conditions is opposed 
 to those claims of publicity and responsibility to the 
 people's representatives, on which democrats have always 
 insisted. The right to criticise officials is the alpha of 
 popular government. It is the worst of sins in a soldier. 
 His first duty is obedience. Partly, perhaps, for this 
 reason our forefathers were apprehensive of a standing 
 army, and took every means of reducing its numbers 
 and powers lest popular liberty should gradually be 
 undermined. It will be time to ridicule their fears 
 when a democratic republic and a vast citizen army 
 shall have existed side by side in France for more than 
 one generation. Actual warfare is, of course, still more 
 fatal to popular government. From the days of Crom- 
 well to those of Bismarck, war has ever tended to exalt 
 the one able leader, and to depress the authority of a 
 Chamber. 
 
 To avert the horrors of war and the political reaction 
 which it entails, states have recourse to diplomacy. But 
 here again democracy enters on a province alien to its 
 true character. Diplomacy demands secrecy and the 
 concession of large discretionary powers to its agents. 
 Democracy demands the discussion of every important 
 compact, even of the steps leading to such compact, by 
 the people's Chamber. Here is the Achilles' heel of 
 popular government, and autocrats have ever aimed 
 their deadliest shafts at this vulnerable point. Recent
 
 238 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 events have brought this fact prominently into notice. 
 In the spring of 1897 the French people were on the 
 horns of a painful dilemma. Their generous instincts 
 bade them befriend the Cretans and Greeks, for whom 
 they have long cherished the liveliest sympathy. On the 
 other hand, their hostility to Germany seemed to impose 
 on them compliance with the dictates of St. Petersburg. 
 Which should they obey, sentiment or interest? Under 
 an autocratic system, such as governs the foreign policy 
 of the central powers, a division of opinion would 
 scarcely be allowed to become apparent: it would be 
 smothered under the secrecy of ministerial discussion. 
 Parliamentary government, on the other hand, required 
 the public discussion of the alternative lines of policy, 
 and ended with a division, which decided for self-interest 
 and against quixotic sentiment. The discussion con- 
 cluded, in this case, with a victory for the diplomatic 
 course of action; but the mere fact of a public official 
 discussion called attention to the division of opinion, 
 and might have encouraged agitators to try to reverse 
 the vote of the Chamber, had the division been less 
 decisive. In any case, all the world knew that the 
 coercive action of France against the Cretan insurgents 
 was not the action of the whole people, but was resisted 
 by a considerable minority. 
 
 The action of our Parliament and of our cabinet at 
 that crisis is not without its features of interest, espe- 
 cially as it may serve to illustrate the advantages of a 
 mixed system of government. A claim similar to that 
 urged in the French chamber was put forward by 
 several members of Parliament, that before our war-ships 
 in Cretan waters took any decided measures of coercion, 
 the sanction of Parliament should be gained. The 
 answer of Mr. Balfour was short and decisive. He 
 emphatically repudiated the claim of Parliament to dic- 
 tate the action of Her Majesty's Ministers on this ques-
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 239 
 
 tion, and stated their determination to act without wait- 
 ing- for any expression of parliamentary opinion. That 
 opinion, or rather public opinion, he said, might be 
 exerted at the next general election, when the country 
 would have the right to endorse or reject their policy; 
 but, for the present, they would act, undeterred by any 
 prospective votes of censure. 
 
 The difference between French and British procedure, 
 in this instance, arose from the fact that the British 
 ministry is, in theory at least, the ministry of the queen 
 as well as of Parliament. On most questions, especially 
 those dependent on money votes, the control of ministers 
 by Parliament is tolerably effective; but in all matters 
 of foreign policy and of administrative action the shield 
 of the monarchy still intervenes between Parliament and 
 the cabinet. Omitting 1 any discussion of the instance 
 cited, it is obviously desirable on broad grounds of 
 expediency that such matters should not be submitted 
 to direct parliamentary control. 
 
 One incident of the reign must be remembered in this 
 connection, as upholding the prerogatives of the crown 
 and preventing- any encroachment even by an able and 
 masterful minister. Lord Palmerston's precipitate action 
 in regard to foreign affairs having produced friction in 
 several cases, Her Majesty, in 1850, sent a sharp re- 
 monstrance to him, requiring his adherence to prescribed 
 customs, and forbidding his interference with any deci- 
 sions previously arrived at or documents drawn up. 
 The secretary of state for foreign affairs accepted the 
 merited rebuke; but on his renewed contravention of this 
 understanding in 1851, when he hastily, though unoffi- 
 cially, recognized and approved Louis Napoleon's coup 
 d'dtat, he was dismissed from office by the premier. 
 The case has a more than personal interest. It marks 
 the resolute maintenance by the crown of a direct influ- 
 ence and control over the details, if not the general
 
 240 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 tenor, of the foreign policy of the United Kingdom; 
 and few will now deny that the intimate knowledge of 
 foreign affairs and of the wishes of rulers, possessed by 
 Her Majesty, renders it most desirable that she should 
 exercise a continuous control such as cannot be in the 
 power of a cabinet minister whose tenure of office de- 
 pends on the vox populi. 
 
 Many cases might be described where our foreign 
 policy has been compromised by publicity. But in days 
 when the South African Committee's inquiry is still 
 fresh in the popular memory it seems needless to dilate 
 on the disadvantages to the public service, or the ad- 
 vantages to proprietors of newspapers, resulting from 
 methods suggested apparently by an admiration for the 
 "chattering Greeks" of the late empire. On the other 
 hand, it may be noted that in proportion to the deter- 
 mination of a British ministry to take energetic action, 
 to that extent is publicity curtailed and the interference 
 of Parliament firmly repelled. The most noteworthy 
 instance of this almost defiant independence shown by 
 our executive is afforded by the action of the Beacons- 
 field ministry in the early part of 1878. The threatening 
 state of affairs at the close of the Russo-Turkish war 
 certainly justified strenuous action. Despite the accep- 
 tance by Turkey of the Russian preliminaries of peace, 
 the czar's troops continued to advance towards the 
 glittering prize of Constantinople. To prevent the 
 seizure of that seat of empire by Russia's legions, the 
 British ministry, without consulting the opinion of Par- 
 liament, immediately took three decisive steps. It 
 ordered the British fleet up the Dardanelles, it de- 
 manded a vote of credit for ^6,000,000 more as a 
 "vote of confidence" than as fixing a definite limit to 
 war expenditure and in the middle of April, when new 
 complications arose, it suddenly ordered a contingent of 
 our Indian troops to sail for Malta. The last order was
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 241 
 
 given only a day after Parliament had been soothed with 
 assurances of a pacific character. 1 
 
 Waiving any discussion of the melodramatic manner 
 in which these decisions were revealed to the world 
 when they were accomplished facts, it will probably be 
 acknowledged by open-minded persons that the swift 
 and determined action of the British government in those 
 four critical months was the best preservative of peace. 
 Without entering into the rights and wrongs of the 
 case, but viewing it merely as a choice of methods in a 
 grave crisis, it can scarcely be doubted that the nation 
 which vacillates and consults is lost, as surely as the 
 general who, in the midst of an engagement, nervously 
 calls a council of war. When the question is thus stated 
 broadly, as a question affecting the efficiency of our 
 diplomatic intervention, only one answer seems to be 
 possible: that while it is the duty of Parliament to 
 supervise the general course of foreign policy and ratify 
 all treaties, yet the conduct of negotiations and the 
 details of any proposed intervention must be left to 
 responsible ministers, who in such contingencies may 
 often be most prudently guided by the advice of the 
 sovereign. 
 
 Objections to this would seem to be founded on sheer 
 confusion of thought as to the real nature of demo- 
 cracy. Such objectors forget that, after all, democracy 
 is only a form of government; 2 that while it assigns 
 to the people a larger share in the representation and 
 in the control of public affairs, yet it differs from mon- 
 archy and aristocracy in degree and not in kind. Neither 
 of these forms of government, in Western Europe at 
 
 1 See Hansard, April 16-19, 1878 ; also Buxton's Finance and Politics, ii. 
 P- 245- 
 
 3 The confusion of thought may in part have arisen from the common 
 blunders of using the word ' ' democracy " as if it were equivalent to ' ' people ", 
 and "people" as equivalent to the "wage-earning classes". "Democracy" 
 means, of course, "government by the people", i.e. the nation.
 
 242 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 least, has ever been totally uninfluenced by public 
 opinion. The pressure of popular feeling has always 
 made itself felt in more or less direct ways on the most 
 absolute of monarchs and the most selfish of oligarchs. 
 Democracy has been mainly concerned with converting 
 this indirect or spasmodic pressure of the multitude on 
 the administration into a direct and regular influence. 
 But it still remains a form of government. It is not a 
 creed of life, as it was to Mazzini. That noble ideal 
 vanished as the smoke of the last discharges of the 
 Roman republicans rolled away on the fatal closing days 
 of June, 1849. The seer, whose winged words had 
 inspired the defenders of Rome no less than Garibaldi's 
 heroism, looked forward to democracy as the initiatrix 
 of a new life, a new civilization. That was not to be. 
 The collision with actuality, the compromises, bargain- 
 ings, and wars that followed, have left democracy merely 
 a form of government, not a life. In the future, when 
 the materialism of the present age has worked itself out, 
 when selfishness has exploited everything within the 
 walls of its prison house, when wars of nations or wars 
 of classes have shattered the bomb-proof bulwarks of 
 the most "civilized" states, then, at last, Humanity will 
 assuredly recur to nobler ideals ; and a new Christendom 
 will arise. For the present, however, democracy is 
 little more than a machine for producing the greatest 
 happiness of the greatest number: it is not an inspira- 
 tion to social duty. The fact must be faced with all its 
 consequences. Chief among these are national jeal- 
 ousies, the resulting military expenditure which imposes 
 the greatest burden on the greatest number, and the 
 mutual fears which attune the Concert of the Powers to 
 lugubrious strains. 
 
 Under these circumstances, popular government must 
 retain many of the characteristics of that of the warring 
 Teutonic tribe. The assent of all the warriors, so
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 243 
 
 Tacitus tells us, was needed for important affairs, but 
 details were discussed by the chiefs in council. The 
 distinction is rooted in the eternal laws of common 
 sense, and can no more be disregarded by the present 
 descendants of Hengist and Cerdic than by their imme- 
 diate followers. Indeed, it is inevitable that the mere 
 increase in the volume and complexity of the nation's 
 concerns should relegate details of foreign policy more 
 and more to the control of the people's chiefs. The 
 division of powers is inevitable, and on the whole is 
 most conducive to the due discharge of legislative 
 business, and to the effective wielding of the nation's 
 power in foreign affairs. 
 
 As a matter of history it cannot be denied that the 
 powers of our cabinet have increased, especially in rela- 
 tion to international policy. The process has been so 
 gradual as to escape general notice, except when some 
 champion of parliamentary forms calls attention to a 
 dangerous innovation. The increase has been partly 
 concealed under the imposing fiction which names the 
 ministers, Her Majesty's ministers. In this as in other 
 respects, monarchical traditions have favoured the steady 
 growth of administrative powers in the hands of the 
 picked men of the predominant party. The advantages 
 of a blending of democracy with monarchy are obvious 
 when we contrast the generally effective control of 
 foreign affairs by our cabinet with the crude efforts of 
 the National Assembly of France in 1790-92 to regulate 
 diplomacy. Ignoring the fact that democracy must 
 under ordinary conditions remain a form of government, 
 it endeavoured first and foremost to reduce the king's 
 ministers to the position of head-clerks, registering the 
 decrees of an all-powerful assembly. After realizing the 
 impossibility of controlling the machinery of government 
 by a crowd of debaters, it next delegated many of its 
 new controlling powers to committees ; and in the con-
 
 244 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 fusion produced by the outbreak of war, these or similar 
 bodies practically absorbed all the executive functions 
 of the state, thus paving the way for the organized 
 bureaucracy of the Directory in 1795-99, and the despot- 
 ism of Napoleon. 
 
 The swiftness of this change may be commended to 
 the notice of all who think that democracy implies 
 the direct management of all public business by a 
 popularly elected Chamber. In relation to the more 
 complex and difficult parts of such business, notably 
 foreign affairs, such a Chamber must be content to act 
 as a final court of appeal, reversing actions that have 
 been emphatically condemned by the electorate, but 
 intrusting to its cabinet ministers and their subordinates 
 the conduct of such affairs as cannot be controlled by 
 a large number of legislators. Among the influences 
 undermining the young French Republic none was more 
 potent than the rabid suspicion of the executive enter- 
 tained by the legislators. In the times of commotion 
 and war that followed, the imperious needs of national 
 safety transferred administrative control to a despotism 
 far heavier than that from which France had escaped. 
 But it is needless to multiply instances. The student 
 of history is well aware that a complete and unmixed 
 democracy has had a lengthy existence only in happy 
 lands, which, as in the case of Switzerland, escape the 
 burdens imposed by a complex foreign policy. Among 
 these favoured countries the United Kingdom cannot be 
 classed. 
 
 Government by public opinion has many recommenda- 
 tions. It is generally far more humane than the policy 
 of diplomatists; and at present the gusts of popular 
 passion would seem to be less dangerous to the welfare 
 of the whole human family than the calculating selfish- 
 ness of governments intent only on their own interests. 
 As the power of the press begins to permeate the more
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 245 
 
 backward of continental peoples, and as facilities of 
 travel mitigate the asperities of national prejudice, it 
 may be hoped that public opinion will everywhere oper- 
 ate with greater power on governmental machinery, and 
 wield it increasingly for the welfare of the whole world, 
 and not merely of the fatherland. At present the pro- 
 gress seems slow, sometimes even it seems to be in the 
 wrong direction. At any rate, the United Kingdom 
 cannot afford to disregard the warnings which are only 
 too clearly visible in the troublous past and the ominous 
 present. While our land has adopted democracy for its 
 internal government, it must retain in foreign policy 
 that administrative machinery which imparts something 
 of consistency to popular desires and strength to the 
 national will. No country can so ill afford to admit 
 flabbiness and vacillation into its external relations. No 
 people has interests so world-wide, a commerce so 
 sensitive, wealth so assailable on all the seas. It stands 
 face to face in the west with a republic, none too friendly, 
 which intrusts vast executive powers to a chief during 
 his four years of office. In the east it is confronted by 
 an all but oriental despotism, which wields all the govern- 
 ing powers of the Caesars, and forces ten times as vast. 
 Lying between these two powers, competing with the 
 one in industry, with the other in policy, Great Britain 
 cannot dispense either with the social invigoration pro- 
 duced by democracy or with the tenacity of purpose 
 developed by monarchical rule. 
 
 Here, then, is a barrier to British democracy which we 
 can scarcely overthrow without abdicating our position 
 as a world-wide power. For other peoples such an 
 abdication would be dangerous, but not suicidal, as it 
 must be to our own. The inhabitants of the United 
 Kingdom live in comfort, not on the resources of these 
 islands alone, but by means of the wealth which their 
 industry and commerce wins from other lands. Only by
 
 246 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 a firm and consistent policy can this easily assailable 
 position be maintained. Hitherto it has been found 
 difficult, if not impossible, for a purely democratic system 
 to sustain a long struggle either in war or diplomacy 
 against a polity constructed primarily with a view to 
 the needs of war or diplomacy. The efforts of our people 
 to cope with these difficulties present some interesting 
 lessons. Specially noteworthy are the events of 1880 
 and of succeeding years. In 1880 it seemed that the 
 people themselves were determined to direct the foreign 
 policy of the land. The complexities of the task soon 
 unfolded themselves. The Gladstone ministry, which 
 was raised to power very largely by the generous 
 enthusiasms of the people in foreign affairs, endeavoured 
 to satisfy those claims. At once it found itself hampered 
 by the obligations of the past and the difficulties of the 
 present ; and before two years were gone it disappointed 
 the wishes of its most ardent supporters by the retention 
 of Cyprus and by intermeddling in the affairs of Egypt. 
 These and many subsequent events have opened the eyes 
 of many who in 1880 had convinced themselves that 
 foreign policy was the offspring of Lord Beaconsfield's 
 oriental imagination and of a desire to divert the nation's 
 energies from domestic reforms into labyrinths of adven- 
 ture. 
 
 The sequel has dispelled those suspicions by reveal- 
 ing the intimate connection between our commercial 
 prosperity and the maintenance of the empire. The 
 earth-hunger of continental states, and their determina- 
 tion to treat their new possessions as strict commercial 
 preserves, have induced the most insular of our manu- 
 facturers to take broader views than were current in the 
 previous generation. For in the meantime free -trade 
 has diffused our commerce and our wealth, thereby com- 
 pelling statesmen to take means of securing it from 
 attack. "Your triumph marks the end of the grand
 
 Democracy and Foreign Policy. 247 
 
 era of English policy": these were the sentiments of 
 M. Renan candidly expressed to Cobden. 1 Events have 
 disproved the charge. The results of free-trade have 
 led our manufacturers and merchants to become Im- 
 perialists. The Little Eng-landers of the previous genera- 
 tion have passed, or are passing, away; and the great 
 manufacturing towns, which were once the strongholds 
 of a somewhat narrow Radicalism, now vie with London 
 and the counties in their desire to maintain our naval 
 supremacy, and to secure the co-operation of all parts 
 of the empire. The Birmingham of John Bright has 
 become the Birmingham of Joseph Chamberlain. 
 
 The changed relations of the United Kingdom to the 
 outside world are realized by the artisans of our great 
 industrial centres. They are becoming increasingly con- 
 scious of the vastness and complexity of British com- 
 mercial interests, on which their livelihood ultimately 
 depends. The imposition of a hostile tariff by a British 
 colony, the annexation of a large slice of Africa by France 
 or Germany, the predominance of Russia in Northern 
 China, may entail ruin on a British industry, or the 
 extinction of a line of steam-ships. In this sphere Trade- 
 unionism is absolutely helpless. Demonstrations and 
 votes of censure will avail nothing unless they move our 
 government to take decisive action. And such action, 
 as I have shown, implies trust on the part of the people 
 in responsible ministers, a trust which not only abstains 
 from crippling their administration of the nation's funds 
 for defensive and offensive purposes, but also enables 
 successive governments to maintain a firm and tenacious 
 foreign policy. 
 
 We have recently been passing (perhaps we have 
 passed) through a phase of thought which is common 
 to every young democratic government, and which 
 wrecked that of France a century ago. The people's 
 
 1 Notes from a Diary, by Sir M. Grant Duff.
 
 248 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 representatives have suspected and nagged at those who 
 are responsible for foreign affairs ; and consequently our 
 policy has been weakened by fits of vacillation such 
 as rarely were known in the time of Pitt, Canning, 
 and Palmerston. If the United Kingdom is to recover 
 its rightful influence in the world, it will be not merely 
 by vast armaments, but by the use of different methods 
 in foreign affairs from those which must necessarily 
 prevail in our domestic concerns. An electorate which 
 is largely inexperienced may, possibly for several decades, 
 enthrone the principle of flux in our home politics; but 
 that same electorate will assuredly learn by bitter ex- 
 perience that unless our foreign policy is firm and con- 
 tinuous, we shall remain without an ally, and be con- 
 demned possibly to an unequal struggle even for the 
 maintenance of our present possessions.
 
 Index. 
 
 Adullamites, the, 174-5, J 77> X 79- 
 Agricultural Holdings Act, 196. 
 Agriculture, British, 19-21, 195- 
 
 203. 
 
 Alabama Case, the, 184. 
 Anti-Corn-law League, 120-1, 125, 
 
 133- 
 
 Arnold, Dr., 114, 127. 
 Artisans' Dwelling Act, 192, 193. 
 Attwood, Thomas, 46, 90-3, 105, 
 
 108. 
 
 Bagehot, Mr., 162. 
 
 Baines, Mr., 75, 170, 179. 
 
 Balfour, Mr., 238. 
 
 Ballot, the, 12, 48, 49, 85, 144, 183, 
 
 191. 
 
 Bamford, Samuel, 28. 
 Beaconsfield, Lord, 198-200, 240. 
 Bentham, Jeremy, 33-5, 152, 154-5. 
 Birkbeck, Dr., 63, 65, 67. 
 Birmingham Political Union, 46, 
 
 90-1, 93. 
 
 Brabrook, Mr., 230. 
 Bright, John, 75, 125, 139, 165, 176, 
 
 178, 190, 205, 246. 
 Brougham, Lord, 39, 59, 98. 
 Bull Ring Riot, the, 106-110. 
 Burdett, Sir Francis, 26, 47. 
 Burke, n, 22. 
 Burns, Mr. John, 229. 
 
 Carlyle, Thomas, 77, 87-8, 94, 114, 
 
 115, 126, 130, 216. 
 Carpenter, William, 73, 103. 
 Cartwright, Major, 12-13, *5> 2 9> 
 
 77, 210. 
 
 Castlereagh, Lord, 64. 
 Chad wick, Mr., 65, 134-5. 
 Chamberlain, Mr., 193, 212, 246. 
 Charter, Origin of the People's, 12, 
 
 15, 24, 28-9, 84-90. 
 Churchill, Ld. Randolph, 206, 233. 
 Cleave, John, 71-3. 
 Cobbett, William, 17, 25-28, 55, 58, 
 
 59, 64, 77, 130. 
 Cobden, Richard, 75, 119-21, 125, 
 
 150, 246. 
 
 Collins, John, 93, 107-8, 116. 
 Combination Laws, Repeal of, 36. 
 Complete Suffrage, 119-128, 203. 
 Constitution, English, 10-13, 3> 
 
 33- 35. 49-52. 78-9, 83-4, 121, 
 
 123, 150-1, 154, 168-171, 205-6, 
 
 210-213, 245. 
 Conventions, Chartist National, 103, 
 
 105, 108, 1 1 1-2, 137-8, 141. 
 Cooper, Thomas, 120, 123, 136. 
 Co-operation, 53-4, 67-8, 144-5, 
 
 221. 
 
 Corn Law, the, of 1815, 23-24. 
 Courtney, Mr., 209. 
 Cross, Viscount, 192. 
 
 Dale, Dr., 205. 
 
 Darwin, 166-7. 
 
 Davitt, Mr., 198. 
 
 Derby, Lord, 175-179, 202. 
 
 Dilke, SirC, 208. 
 
 Disraeli, Mr., 55-59, 150, 172, 176 
 
 181, 185, 187-194, 196-198. 
 Drage, Mr., M.P., 215, 227. 
 
 Eastern Question, the, 198-9, 237- 
 8, 240, 245.
 
 250 
 
 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Education Act of 1870, the, 183, 
 
 185. 
 
 Eight Hours Day, 224-230. 
 Elliott, Ebenezer, 65. 
 Emancipation, Catholic, 36. 
 Engel, Karl, 135. 
 
 Fabian Society, the, 224-7, 2 34- 
 Factory Acts, 193, 218-224, 226. 
 Fielden, Mr., 55, 95, 139, 219. 
 Firth, Mr., 205. 
 Forster, W. E., 183-4. 
 Fox, C. J., 12, 22. 
 Free-trade, 192, 195. 
 Friendly Societies Act, 193. 
 Frost, Mr., 112. 
 
 Gladstone, Mr., 150, 169-175, 179- 
 186, 187-192, 196-7, 199-200, 
 205-210, 212, 231. 
 
 Grey, Earl, 39, 186. 
 
 Grote, George, 73, 74, 183. 
 
 Ground Game Act, the, 203. 
 
 Hampden Clubs, 28-9. 
 Hardie, Mr. Keir, 229. 
 Hare, Mr., 161-4, I 79- 
 Harney, G. J., 102, 103, 140-1, 
 
 143, 144. 
 
 Hartington, Lord, 212. 
 Hetherington, Henry, 71-3, 77, 
 
 87, 89, 96, 101, 214-5. 
 Hodgkin, Lieutenant, 43-5, 53, 
 
 100, 214-5. 
 Holyoake, Mr., 91. 
 Home Rule, 187-8, 197, 212, 231. 
 Howell, Mr., M.P., 223, 225. 
 Hughes, Thomas, 144-5. 
 Hume, Joseph, 35, 37, 39, 80, 142. 
 Hunt, Henry, 26, 30-2, 55, 77. 
 
 Independent Labour Party, 229. 
 Irish Church, Disestablishment of 
 
 the, 186. 
 Irish Land Act of 1870, 182, 186, 
 
 190, 196. 
 
 Jacobins, 12-13, T S- 
 
 Jones, Ernest, 140-1, 143, 144. 
 
 Kingsley, Rev. Charles, 138, 144-5, 
 
 221. 
 
 Knight, Charles, 64. 
 Kossuth, 143. 
 
 Laing, Mr., 179. 
 
 Local Government Bill, the, of 
 1888, 212-3. 
 
 Locke King, 170. 
 
 Lodger Franchise, 178, 210. 
 
 London Working Men's Associa- 
 tion, 74, 86, 101, 116, 215. 
 
 Lovett, William, 64, 66-9, 77, 85- 
 87, 96-7, 107-8, in, 116-7, 124, 
 142, 214-5. 
 
 Lowe, Robert, 174-5, l8 4i I ^9- 
 
 Lubbock, Sir John, 209. 
 
 Lytton, Bulwer, 74. 
 
 Macaulay, Lord, 158. 
 
 Maine, Sir Henry, 211. 
 
 Mallock, Mr. W. H., 230. 
 
 Malthus, Dr., 56-7. 
 
 Mann, Mr. Tom, 227. 
 
 Martineau, Miss, 57, 64. 
 
 Maurice, Rev. F. D., 115, 144-5, 
 
 221. 
 
 Mazzini, 87-9, 116, 142, 236, 241. 
 Melbourne, Lord, 51, 81, 82, 186. 
 Miall, Edward, 121-2, 127, 183. 
 Mill, James, 35-8, 157. 
 Mill, John Stuart, 35-6, 96, 152, 
 
 ISS. IS7-I66, 173-4, 179. 183-4, 
 
 209. 
 
 Milner Gibson, Mr., 75. 
 Molesworth, Sir W., 74. 
 Montesquieu, 150, 154. 
 Moral -force Chartists, 87-90, 96, 
 
 103-4, IJ S' II8 - l8 3> 2l8 > 22 4- 
 Morley, Mr. John, 205, 231. 
 Municipal Reform Act, 61. 
 
 Napoleon I., 13-14. 
 National Debt, 16, 190.
 
 Index. 
 
 251 
 
 National Political Union, 46-9. 
 National Union of the Working 
 
 Classes, 45, 47-9. 
 Newport Riot, the, 112-4. 
 Noble, John, 202. 
 Northcote, Sir Stafford, 208. 
 Northern Star, the, 100-1, 106, 
 
 117, 144, 215. 
 
 Oastler, Mr., 95, 100, 102, 219. 
 O'Brien, Bronterre, 101, 105, in, 
 
 216. 
 
 O'Connell, 26, 86-97. 
 O'Connor, Feargus, 96, 97-101, 103, 
 
 in, 117, 118, 122-5, 136, 139-141, 
 
 143-4, 146, 203, 215. 
 Outrages, the Sheffield, 221-2. 
 Owen, Robert, 18, 41-3, 47, 53-4, 
 
 67, 73, 87-8, 96, 215-216, 217, 
 
 219. 
 
 Paine, Tom, 26. 
 
 Palmerston, Lord, 51, 148, 150, 169, 
 
 186, 239, 247. 
 Parliament, Reform of, 32, 33, 35- 
 
 40, 45-52, 83-4, 85-6, 93, 121, 
 
 123, 144-6, 161-5, 168-171, 221-2, 
 233- 
 
 Peel, Sir Robert, 18, 51, 81, no, 
 
 121, 127, 130-5, 147, 149, 150, 
 
 219. 
 
 Peterloo, 15, 31-2. 
 Physical - force Chartists, 28, 90, 
 
 97-105, 108-114, I 35~4 I > 22I> 
 Pitt, William, 13, 22, 150, 247. 
 Place, Francis, 40-41, 44, 46, 87, 
 
 117. 
 
 Plug Riots, the, 123-4. 
 Police Bill, the, no. 
 Poor Law, 52, 54-62, 77-8, 93-6, 
 
 134. 
 Proudhon, 43. 
 
 Reform Bill, the, of 1832, 32, 33- 
 9, 48-52, 83, 130, 151, 158, 188, 
 205. 
 
 Reform Bill of 1866, 167-175. 
 
 Reform Bill of 1867, 176-181, 186-9, 
 201-4, 2 6> 2 33- 
 
 Reform Bills of 1884-5, 200-212, 
 
 233- 
 Representative Government, Mill's, 
 
 161-165. 
 Revolution, French, of 1789, 12, 18- 
 
 19- 33. 48. 
 Revolution, French, of 1830, 36, 
 
 39- 
 
 Roebuck, Mr., 86, 123. 
 Rousseau, 34, 152, 153-4. 
 Russell, Lord John, 46, 48, 82-4, 
 
 85, 108, in, 112, 169-72, 174-6, 
 
 179. 
 
 ' ' Sacred Month ", the, 45, 104, 
 
 105. 
 
 Sadler, Michael, Mr., 95, 219. 
 Salisbury, Lord, 178-9, 207-8, 212. 
 Shaftesbury, Lord, 55, 139, 219- 
 
 220. 
 
 Shaw, Mr. Bernard, 232. 
 Six Acts, the, 32. 
 Smith, Adam, 55. 
 Smith, Sydney, 57, 63, 82. 
 Spence, Dr., 100, 216. 
 Spencer, Herbert, 166. 
 Spring Rice, Mr., 74, 82. 
 Stephens, Raynor, Rev., 94-6, 100, 
 
 123. 
 
 St. Simon, 167. 
 Sturge, Joseph, no, 118-128, 203. 
 
 "Taxes on Knowledge", 63-5, 70- 
 
 6, 168-9. 
 
 Taylor, Dr. J. , 102, 105, 107. 
 Ten Hours Act, 139, 219. 
 Tocqueville, de, 151-3, 156-7. 
 "Tom Hughes", 144-5. 
 Tooke, Home, 12-13. 
 Trade-unions, 53-4, 123, 145, 184, 
 
 220-230; the new, 224-232. 
 Trevelyan, Sir G., 200-1. 
 
 Unionism, the new, 224-232. 
 Unstamped Press, the, 64-73. 
 
 Victoria, Queen, 79-81, 239.
 
 252 
 
 The Rise of Democracy. 
 
 Villiers, Mr., 75. 
 
 Vincent, Henry, 66, 69-71, 87, 89, 
 97, 101, 104, in, no. 
 
 Wade, Dr., 90, 103. 
 
 Watson, James, 73. 
 Webb, Mr. Sidney, 224-7. 
 Wellington, Duke of, 39, 46, no, 
 
 138- 
 William IV., 80, 86. 
 
 PRINTED BY BLACKIE AND SON, LIMITED, GLASGOW
 
 of California 
 
 A REG '? NAL LIBRA Y FACIUTY 
 Avenue, Los Angeles, CA 90024-1388 
 Return this material to the library 
 whteh It was borrowed 
 
 197* 
 
 Form
 
 t 
 
 THIS BOOK CARD 
 
 runi 
 
 u 
 
 University Research Library 
 
 DA 
 
 ru 
 
 2)
 
 . 
 
 - - - . 
 
 :'. . '. ' 
 
 - 3 . a 
 , 
 
 ; ' > 
 
 -.'- 
 
 ' ^1