THE LIBRARY 
 
 OF 
 
 THE UNIVERSITY 
 
 OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 IRVINE 
 
 GIFT OF 
 JERRY ROHACEK 

 
 G. G. rACLElS

 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS
 
 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY 
 
 NEW YORK BOSTON CHICAGO 
 ATLANTA SAN FRANCISCO 
 
 MACMILLAN & CO., LIMITED 
 
 LONDON BOMBAY CALCUTTA 
 MELBOURNE 
 
 THE MACMILLAN CO. OF CANADA, LTD. 
 
 TORONTO
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 (REVISED EDITION) 
 
 RICHARD T. JELY, PH.D., LL.D. 
 
 PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOMY IN THE UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN 
 
 REVISED AND ENLARGED BY 
 THE AUTHOR 
 
 AND 
 
 THOMAS S. ADAMS, PH.D. 
 
 PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOMY IN THE UNIVERSITY 
 OF WISCONSIN 
 
 MAX O. LORENZ, PH.D. 
 
 ASSISTANT PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOMY IN THE UNIVERSITY 
 
 OF WISCONSIN; DEPUTY COMMISSIONER IN THE WISCONSIN 
 
 BUREAU OF LABOR AND INDUSTRIAL STATISTICS 
 
 ALLYN A. YOUNG, PH.D. 
 
 PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS IN LELAND STANFORD JUNIOR 
 UNIVERSITY 
 
 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY 
 1909 
 
 All rights reserved
 
 COPYRIGHT, 1893, 
 BY HUNT & EATON. 
 
 COPYRIGHT, 1908, 
 BY THE MACMILLAN COMPANY. 
 
 First published elsewhere. Reprinted May, 1900; July, October, 
 1901; August, 1903; July, September, 1904; July, 1905; January, 
 August, 1906; July, 1907; April, 1908. 
 
 New edition, revised and enlarged, September, October, 1908; 
 January, August, 1909. 
 
 Xoriuooti 
 
 J. 8. Cashing Co. Berwick & Smith Co. 
 Norwood, Mass., U.S.A.
 
 PREFACE 
 
 SINCE the first edition of the Outlines of Economics was pub- 
 lished fifteen years ago, there has been considerable progress in 
 economic discussion. In this revision an attempt has been made 
 to include so much of the new thought as seems to have established 
 itself. No chapters remain unaltered, most of them have been 
 entirely rewritten, and some new ones have been added. But the 
 plan of the former edition has been retained. This book differs 
 from the Elementary Principles of Economics, published in 1904 
 by Ely and Wicker, in that it is a more advanced treatise, and in- 
 tended primarily for college and university use; whereas the latter, 
 although used in a number of higher institutions, is intended pri- 
 marily for high schools. 
 
 Four persons have taken part in this revision, but a free inter- 
 change of criticism has, it is hoped, resulted in a unified product. 
 
 Numerous passages, amounting in the aggregate to many pages, 
 have been printed in smaller type. Such are the passages which, 
 either from their greater difficulty or from their subsidiary char- 
 acter, may best be omitted by a teacher pressed for time. More- 
 over, for classes in which the time limits are too narrow to permit 
 careful study of the whole text, it may be found expedient to omit 
 Book III, on Public Finance ; while, on the other hand, some 
 teachers may wish to take this Book up for independent study. 
 
 Considerable attention has been given to the questions at the 
 close of each chapter, and an endeavor has been made to frame 
 these so as to require a mastery of principles to answer them. 
 Perusal of the text alone will not enable one to answer them all. 
 In some cases it will be necessary to use the references to literature 
 given at the close of chapters. There are also cases in which the 
 correct answer must be a matter open to differences of opinion. 
 It is hoped and believed that the questions will give rise to fruitful 
 class discussions.
 
 VI PREFACE 
 
 The aim of the authors has been to cover the entire field of eco- 
 nomics, feeling that in this way they best serve the purposes of 
 those students who are going to carry their studies further as well 
 as those whose systematic school study of economics will end with 
 the present treatise. 
 
 At certain points in the discussion of distribution, use has been 
 made of the so-called "productivity theory." In order that there 
 may be no misapprehension, it may be well to say here, what is 
 repeated in the text, that in our view this theory has little or no 
 ethical significance, and that its principal value is as an expeditious 
 method of approaching the supply and demand theory, with which 
 it is in complete harmony. When properly handled, it has the 
 pedagogical virtue of leading the student directly to a study of the 
 innumerable forces which condition supply and demand. But to 
 regard the productivity theory as an end, is to mistake the problem 
 for its solution; and to pass from this theory lightly to the imme- 
 diate solution of those problems which the theory of distribution 
 is designed to explain, is to offer, in place of scientific explanation, 
 a mass of pretentious platitudes. 
 
 Valuable suggestions have been received from Dr. H. C. Taylor 
 and from Dr. W. H. Price, both of the University of Wisconsin. 
 
 In conclusion, I wish to express my high appreciation of the 
 work of my friends and colleagues in the revision of this book. 
 
 RICHARD T. ELY. 
 MADISON, WISCONSIN, 
 July, 1908.
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 BOOK I. INTRODUCTION 
 
 PACK 
 
 PREFACE v 
 
 CHAPTER I. THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Diversity of economic study, 3 ; Definition of economics, 4 ; A 
 social science, 5 ; Studies man in process of development, 6 ; Econo- 
 mic laws, 7 ; Principal divisions of economics, 15. 
 
 CHAPTER II. THE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE PRESENT ECONOMIC 
 SYSTEM 
 
 Human and physical conditions of economic activity, 16 ; Private 
 enterprise and state activity, 1 6 ; Division of labor and exchange, 
 18; Mutual dependence, 19; Economic classes, 19 ; Private prop- 
 erty, 20; Inheritance, 21; Contract, 21 ; Vested interests, 22; 
 Freedom, 23 ; Competition and markets, 24 ; Cooperation, 26 ; 
 Monopoly, 26 ; Custom, 27 ; Authority and benevolence, 27. 
 
 CHAPTER III. THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 
 
 Basis of the economic stages, 29 ; Direct appropriation, 30 ; 
 Primitive man, 31; Pastoral stage, 32; Agricultural stage, 33; 
 Manorial economy in England, 34 ; Handicraft stage, 35 ; Gilds, 
 35 ; Domestic system, 36 ; Agricultural changes, 37 ; The mercan- 
 tile system, 37 ; Patents of monopoly, 38 ; Industrial stage, 39 ; 
 Other classifications, 39. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY (Continued} 
 
 England in 1760, 43 ; Revolt against restrictions, 43 ; Mechani- 
 cal inventions, 44 ; Agricultural changes, 46 ; Effects of industrial 
 revolution, 47 ; The factory system, 47 ; Expansion of markets and 
 industrial specialization, 48 ; Evils of the transition, 48 ; Competi- 
 tion and laissez-faire, 49 ; Reaction against the passive policy, 50 ; 
 Quality of goods, 50 ; Protection of labor, 51 ; Labor organizations, 
 53 ; Extension of government enterprise, 54..
 
 Viii CONTENTS 
 
 CHAPTER V. THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
 
 Economic stages in American industrial history, 56 ; Sectional- 
 ism, 57 ; Characteristics of the American people, 58 ; Growth of 
 population, 59 ; Changes in the birth rate, 60 ; Slavery and the 
 negro problem, 6l ; Immigration, 62 ; Natural resources, 66. 
 
 CHAPTER VI. THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED 
 STATES {Continued") 
 
 Mercantilism in America, 70; American industries in 1776, 72 ; 
 The Industrial Revolution in America, 72 ; The development of 
 agriculture, 75 ; Manufactures, 76 ; Transportation, 80 ; The labor 
 movement, 83 ; State regulation of industry, 86. 
 
 BOOK II. PRINCIPLES AND PROBLEMS 
 
 PART I. INTRODUCTION 
 CHAPTER VII. ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 
 
 Motives in economic activity, 93 ; Utility, 95 ; Free and econo- 
 mic goods, 95; Effort, 96; Waiting, 96; Services, 96; Personal 
 qualities as goods, 97 ; Wealth, 98 ; Wealth and income, 98 ; In- 
 dividual and society, 98 ; Wealth and value, 99 ; Capital and other 
 forms of wealth, 100 ; Capital goods and capital value, loo ; Social 
 and individual capital, 101 ; National wealth and national divi- 
 dend, 101. 
 
 PART II. CONSUMPTION 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. CONSUMPTION 
 
 Consumption denned, 106 ; Productive and final consumption, 
 106 ; Human wants, 107 ; Law of diminishing utility, 107 ; Differ- 
 ent uses for the same commodity, 108 ; Marginal utility, 108 ; The 
 economic order of consumption, 1 10 ; Future wants, 1 1 1 ; Alleged 
 present consumption of future products, H2; Consumption and 
 saving, 113; Luxury, 113; Ideal distribution of wealth, 114; 
 Harmful consumption, 116; Statistics of consumption, 117. 
 
 PART III. PRODUCTION 
 
 CHAPTER IX. PRODUCTION 
 
 Production defined, 121 ; The factors of production, 122 ; Saving 
 and capital formation, 123 ; Production and sacrifice, 124; Cost of 
 production and expense of production, 125 ; Separation in owner- 
 ship and organization of factors, 126 ; The undertaker, 127 ; Kinds
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 of division of labor, 127; Advantages of division of labor, 128; 
 Effect upon the worker and the product, 129; Territorial division 
 of labor, 131 ; Productive organization of the American people, 132. 
 
 CHAPTER X. BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 Nature of business units, 136; The corporation charter, 141; 
 Corporation capital and securities, 143 ; Overcapitalization, 144 ; 
 Forms of capitalization, 146 ; Corporation management, 147 ; Ad- 
 vantages and social aspects of corporations, 148; Trusts, 150; 
 Publicity, 153; Federal control, 154. 
 
 PART IV. VALUE AND EXCHANGE 
 CHAPTER XI. VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 Meaning and significance of value, 156 ; The market, 158 ; Con- 
 ditions of competitive valuation, 159; Supply and demand, 160; 
 Nature of demand, 160; Elasticity of demand, 163; Consumer's 
 surplus, 164; Nature of supply, 165 ; The determination of price, 
 167 ; Producer's surplus, 169. 
 
 CHAPTER XII. VALUE AND PRICE {Continued} 
 
 Normal value, 170; Different conditions of supply, 172; Con- 
 stant and variable expenses, 174; Joint expenses of production, 
 177; Surplus of bargaining, 177; Non-reproducible goods, 178; 
 Monopoly value, 1 79 ; Retail prices, 1 79 ; Public authority and 
 value, 179; Imputed value, 181 ; Valuation of production goods, 
 182; Other theories of value, 183. 
 
 CHAPTER XIII. MONOPOLY 
 
 The idea of monopoly, 187; Partial monopoly, 191 ; Classifica- 
 tion and causes, 192 ; Public and private, 193 ; Social and natural, 
 194 ; Local, national, and international, 196 ; monopoly price, 197 ; 
 Law of monopoly price, 201 ; Class price, 202 ; Monopoly price, 
 high price, 206 ; Monopolies and distribution of wealth, 208 ; 
 Public policy toward monopolies, 209 ; Relation of monopoly to 
 trusts, 211. 
 
 CHAPTER XIV. MONEY 
 
 Definitions, 214 ; Metallic money, 216 ; Coinage, 217; Seignior- 
 age, 217; The standard of value, 221; Limited coinage, 224; 
 Bimetallism, 225 ; The gold standard, 234 ; Government paper 
 money, 234 ; Colonial and Revolutionary bills of credit, 235 ; The 
 greenbacks, 236 ; Hat money, 241.
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 CHAPTER XV CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 Credit transactions, 243 ; Personal credit, 246 ; Bank credit, 247 ; 
 Bank notes, 250 ; State banks of issue, 250 ; The national banking 
 system, 251; The reserve system, 252; The New York money 
 market, 253 ; Speculation and the New York money market, 255 ; 
 The independent treasury system, 257 ; The movement of money, 
 258 ; Elastic currency, 260 ; A central bank, 262 ; State and pri- 
 vate banks, 263. 
 
 CHAPTER XVI. OTHER PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 Crises, 267 ; Effects of changes in the value of money, 270 ; 
 
 The standard of deferred payments, 271 ; Index numbers, 272; 
 
 The value of money, 275 ; The production of gold, 280. 
 
 CHAPTER XVII. INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 Nature and advantages of international trade, 284 ; Law of com- 
 parative costs, 285 ; Restrictions on international trade, 286 ; Bal- 
 ance of trade, 288 ; Foreign exchange, 292 ; Regulation of gold 
 supply, 296. 
 
 CHAPTER XVIII. PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 
 The case for protection, 300 ; Arguments of free-traders, 305 ; 
 Conclusions, 311. 
 
 PART V. DISTRIBUTION 
 
 CHAPTER XIX. DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 Distribution controlled by existing institutions, 317; The dis- 
 tributive process, 318; Distribution as valuation, 319; Law of 
 diminishing productivity, 319-326 ; Marginal productivity, 326- 
 331 ; Marginal productivity and valuation, 331 ; Social aspects of 
 diminishing productivity, 332. 
 
 CHAPTER XX. THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 Wealth and income, 335 ; Absolute and relative well being, 335 ; 
 Concentration of wealth and large scale production, 335 ; Methods 
 of measuring concentration of wealth and income, 336 ; Statistics 
 of distribution, 337 ; Causes of poverty and riches, 341 ; The diffu- 
 sion of wealth, 343 ; Modifying wealth acquisition, 345. 
 
 CHAPTER XXI. THE RENT OF LAND 
 
 The services of land, 349 ; Rent under uniform intensivity of cul- 
 tivation, 351; Rent under actual conditions, 354; The different 
 uses of land, 357 ; The capitalization of rent, 359 ; Rent and social 
 progress, 360 ; The unearned increment, 363 ; Urban lands, 365.
 
 CONTENTS xi 
 
 CHAPTER XXII. THE WAGES OF LABOR 
 
 Wages as the price of labor, 367 ; Demand for labor, 368 ; Labor 
 saving machinery, 369 ; Supply of labor, 371 ; Growth of popula- 
 tion, 373 ; Subsistence theory of wages, 376 ; The standard of life 
 and wages, 377 ; Supply of labor in different occupations, 380 ; 
 The wage contract, 381 ; Wages and efficiency, 382. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIII. LABOR PROBLEMS 
 
 Types of labor organizations, 387 ; Jurisdiction disputes, 388 ; 
 Economic justification of labor organizations, 389 ; Labor organiza- 
 tions and monopoly, 390 ; Methods and policies of labor organiza- 
 tions, 391 ; Educational and fraternal activities, 394 ; The strike, 
 395 ; Employers' associations, 400 ; Agencies of industrial peace, 
 401 ; Trade arbitration, 403 ; Voluntary arbitration, 404 ; Com- 
 pulsory arbitration, 404 ; Profit sharing, 406 ; Industrial democracy, 
 408 ; Cooperation, 409. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV. INTEREST 
 
 Definition, 416; Inadequate explanations, 417; Why interest 
 can be paid, 418 ; The necessity of interest, 419 ; The investment 
 and replacement of capital, 420-428 ; The expense and value of 
 capital, 428 ; Capital and land, 431 ; Capital and consumption 
 goods, 434 ; The rate of interest, 435 ; Gross and net interest, 437. 
 
 CHAPTER XXV. PROFITS 
 
 The entrepreneur's wage, 440; Speculative gains, 441 ; Chance 
 gains, 445 ; Gains of bargaining, 446 ; Non-competitive profits, 
 446 ; The social dividend, 448. 
 
 PART VI. THE RELATION OF THE STATE TO INDUSTRY 
 
 CHAPTER XXVI. NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 
 
 The state and the meaning of state activity, 458 ; State and gov- 
 ernment, 459 ; Purity and efficiency of the state in relation to eco- 
 nomic activity, 459 ; general statement of the necessity of state 
 activity, 460 ; The state and the fundamental institutions of society, 
 460 ; Property, private and public, 461 ; trade-marks, copyrights, 
 and patents, 463 ; Public property, 465 ; Inheritance of property, 
 466 ; Contract, 466 ; Ethical level of competition, 467 ; The con- 
 sumer, 467 ; Monopolies, government ownership, etc., 468 ; The 
 state as the guardian of the permanent interests of society, 468.
 
 xii CONTENTS 
 
 CHAFFER XXVII. TRANSPORTATION 
 
 Scope and significance, 471 ; The railway system of the United 
 States, 472 ; Railway competition, 473 ; Pooling and consolidation, 
 475 ; The movement of rates, 475 ; The level of rates, 477 ; Rela- 
 tive rates, 478 ; Distance, 480 ; Government ownership, 479 ; 
 Regulation of railways, 481 ; The Interstate Commerce Commis- 
 sion, 483. 
 
 CHAPTER XXVIII. INSURANCE 
 
 Nature of insurance, 485 ; Law of probabilities, 486 ; Origin and 
 development, 486 ; Forms of insurance organization, 489 ; Life 
 tables, 490; The reserve, 491 ; The surplus, 491 ; Endowments, 
 492 ; Industrial insurance, 493 ; State insurance, 493 ; State regu- 
 lation, 494. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIX. ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 
 
 Importance of municipal activity, 496 ; Character of municipal 
 activities, 498 ; Protection through competition, 501 ; Methods of 
 public regulation, 503 ; Municipal management, 507 ; Municipal 
 home rule, 512. 
 
 CHAPTER XXX. SOCIALISM 
 
 Socialism defined, 515; Distributive justice, 515; Varieties of 
 socialism, 516 ; Communism, 519 ; Socialism an extension of exist- 
 ing institutions, 519; The strength of socialism, 520; The weak- 
 ness of socialism, 521 ; Social reform, 523 ; The socialist movement, 
 524 ; Anarchism, 525. 
 
 CHAPTER XXXI. AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 
 
 Size of farms, 528 ; Ownership and tenancy, 533'; Farm labor, 
 536 ; Farm indebtedness and agricultural credit, 538 ; Tenancy vs. 
 encumbered ownership, 540 ; Marketing of farm products, 543 ; 
 Speculation, 546 ; Education and organization, 548. 
 
 BOOK III. PUBLIC FINANCE 
 
 CHAPTER XXXII. PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 
 Nature and significance of public finance, 555 ; Expenditures of 
 public and private economics contrasted, 558; The proper propor- 
 tion between the total income of society and public expenditures, 
 560; Economy vs. parsimony, 564; Historical development, 566; 
 Development of public expenditures with respect to regularity and 
 irregularity, 570; Terms used in public expenditures, 572; Classi- 
 fication of public expenditures, 573.
 
 CONTENTS xiii 
 
 CHAFFER XXXIII. PUBLIC REVENUES FROM LOANS AND 
 GOVERNMENT OWNERSHIP 
 
 Classification, 580 ; Temporary revenues and public debts, 582 ; 
 Public domains, 586; Land policy of the United States, 587; Forest 
 lands, 589; Mineral lands, 591; Success of our land policy, 593; 
 Land nationalization and municipalization, public industries, 595; 
 Public industries, 597. 
 
 CHAPTER XXXIV. PUBLIC REVENUES: DERIVATIVE REVENUES, 
 FEES, SPECIAL ASSESSMENTS, AND TAXES 
 
 Definitions, 605; Fees, 606; Special assessments, 608; Taxes, 
 610; Justice in taxation, 612; Progressive taxation, 616; The 
 shifting of taxes, 619. 
 
 CHAPTER XXXV. PUBLIC REVENUES: FEDERAL, STATE, AND 
 LOCAL TAXES 
 
 Direct and indirect taxes, 625; Customs duties, 627; Internal 
 revenue duties, 631 ; Taxes on transactions, 633; Inheritance taxes, 
 637; General property tax, 640; Corporation taxes, 645; Business 
 and license taxes, 648; Poll taxes, 649; Federal control of taxa- 
 tion of interstate commerce, 650; Separation of sources of state and 
 local revenues, 651. 
 
 BOOK IV. HISTORY OF ECONOMIC 
 THOUGHT 
 
 CHAPTER XXXVI. HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 
 
 The development of economic thought, 657 ; Economic ideas in 
 the ancient world, 658 ; The Middle Ages, 661 ; Modern times, 
 662 ; Adam Smith, 664 ; The classical school, 665 ; Socialism, 
 668 ; The sociologists, 669 ; The historical school, 669 ; The eco- 
 nomic optimists, 670 ; Early American economists, 672 ; The 
 Austrian school, 673 ; Present condition of economic thought, 674. 
 
 APPENDIX A : Statistics of Public Expenditure 677 
 
 APPENDIX B : Subjects for Essays and Courses of Reading . . . 685 
 INDEX 697
 
 BOOK I 
 INTRODUCTION
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 CHAPTER I 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 
 
 THE most striking characteristics of the great field of knowledge 
 the Outlines of which we attempt to sketch in the present volume 
 are its rich diversity and spacious amplitude. Starting from psychol- 
 ogy in its analysis of the human needs which explain or condition 
 wealth, it traverses the entire field of social activities and institu- 
 tions arising from man's efforts to supply his material needs. It 
 touches on one side the physical sciences from which it borrows 
 some of its most fundamental principles; occupies joint terri- 
 tory at places with politics, ethics, and law, although their 
 respective jurisdictions are in the main distinct; and forms at 
 once the most fertile and most thoroughly developed province of 
 the broad science of human society. Within its borders, if we 
 may continue to compare the scientific possibilities of economics 
 with the natural resources of an opulent territory, opportunity is 
 offered for the exercise of every mental aptitude and every scientific 
 method. The historian's gift is needed to unravel the past and 
 trace the development of the industrial institutions whose present- 
 day problems, in turn, offer indefinite scope for the studies of the 
 more practical student with a taste for administration or business 
 management. For the legal mind there are the subtle problems 
 of property, inheritance, labor legislation, and corporation control; 
 for the mathematically inclined, insurance and modern statistics; 
 for students with practical political interests, the tariff, currency 
 reform, and a score of important problems in which economics 
 and politics are inextricably interwoven; for the philanthropic, 
 unemployment, accident insurance, and a number of social prob- 
 
 3
 
 4 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 lems growing out of the maladjustments of modern industry. 
 Animating the entire subject, blended of course with the love of 
 truth for truth's sake common to all sciences, is the persistent 
 hope that by systematic study we may eventually abolish the ma- 
 terial poverty which deadens and dwarfs the lives of millions of 
 our fellows. Economics is a science, but something more than a 
 science; a science shot through with the infinite variety of human 
 life, calling not only for systematic, ordered thinking, but for 
 human sympathy, imagination, and in an unusual degree for the 
 saving grace of common sense. 
 
 To define such a subject adequately in a few sentences is mani- 
 festly impossible. It is frequently said that economics treats of 
 man's efforts to earn a living, and this definition is not inaccurate 
 if by "man" we understand "mankind," and if we fully appre- 
 ciate that the individual's efforts to turn an honest penny's profit 
 receive but little attention in comparison with the community's 
 efforts to feed, clothe, and shelter itself. Satisfaction of social 
 need, and not individual profit, is the objective point of the science. 
 So, similarly, economics has been characterized as the philosophy 
 of human industry; and this description is illuminating provided 
 we interpret "industry" broadly enough. Even the old tradi- 
 tional definition, that economics is the science of wealth, is true 
 enough if we clearly understand that there can be no wealth with- 
 out man, and that the science which deals with wealth, so far 
 from being a "gospel of mammon," necessarily begins and ends 
 in the study of man. As we prefer to define it, however, econo- 
 mics is the science which treats of those social phenomena that are 
 due to the wealth-getting and wealth-using activities of man. 
 
 Economics treats of Man. The supreme importance of man 
 in the study of wealth has not always been appreciated by those 
 who have expounded the science. Too often they have considered 
 man simply as a producer of wealth, the one "by whom" the 
 necessaries, conveniences, and luxuries of life are created, whereas 
 the infinitely greater truth is that man is the one "for whom" 
 they are all produced. Of course no one denies this truth, but 
 one might almost as well deny it as to leave it out of account. 
 The result of such neglect is that men devise with great skill
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 5 
 
 rules by which man may be made the best possible manufactur- 
 ing machine. It sometimes quite escapes the notice of these 
 persons that in making man the best possible manufacturing 
 machine they may make him a very poor sort of a man; that in 
 teaching him to supply his wants very bountifully they may pre- 
 vent his developing and correcting those same wants. They for- 
 get that there are two kinds of poverty one a lack of goods for 
 the higher wants, the other a lack of wants for the higher goods. 
 To become rich in goods while losing at the same time the power 
 to profit by them is unfortunately one of the commonest retro- 
 gressions in human experience. We do not mean that the whole 
 problem of human development is the subject of economics, but 
 simply that manhood, rounded human development, is the goal 
 of all social sciences, and none must consider their subject so 
 narrowly as to exclude that object. 
 
 Another common mistake has been to regard as of chief im- 
 portance the economic activities of one particular class, especially 
 the employer. Other men were treated simply as "a factor in 
 production." An English writer speaks of dear labor as one of 
 the chief obstacles to England's economic prosperity. Could 
 anything be more utterly an oversight of general human well- 
 being? Dear labor should be the very goal of England's eco- 
 nomic effort, for that means abundant supply of the wants of the 
 great mass of her people ; and the fact that labor is dear, so far 
 from being an obstacle to prosperity, is the very proof and sub- 
 stance of that prosperity. A glance at history indicates that men 
 have made these mistakes not only in theory but in practice. 
 Industries have been developed to majestic proportions while 
 man was sinking into deeper degradation ; wealth has grown 
 at the expense of that human weal in whose service it won its 
 name. 
 
 Economics treats of Man in Society. This is one of those 
 truisms which only history can make real to us. As we pass from 
 the savage and cannibal, up through all the stages of development, 
 we find an ever-increasing interdependence among men. Man is 
 least dependent when he wants least, cares least, has least, knows 
 least, and is least. With every betterment of condition and char-
 
 6 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 acter he/ is more dependent than before, more dependent and yet 
 more free. The beginnings of barter are a confession of mutual 
 need; the coining of money is a declaration of dependence to all 
 men. We look with pride upon a century of progress, but that 
 progress has consisted in little else than a growth of dependence, 
 an ever-increasing departure from that rude kind of literal self- 
 help in which each one does everything for himself. Our fathers 
 drew water, each for himself, in "the moss-covered bucket," while 
 our mothers dipped candles for the evening's light. If one was 
 negligent, the rest did not suffer. To-day a network of pipes radi- 
 ate from a common center to enter a thousand households. An 
 engineer makes a blunder at the station, and thousands are in 
 darkness or drought. Progress is a passage from independence 
 to dependence, from distrust to confidence, from hostility to amity, 
 from helplessness to helpfulness, while the great law of social 
 solidarity gains ever-increasing importance. Our science, then, 
 is interested primarily in man in his relations to others, and not 
 in man by himself. Moreover, as a science which studies the pres- 
 ent in order that it may predict and prepare for the future, and 
 discovering that interdependence is the law of progress, it must 
 not hesitate to shape its principles with reference to a solidarity 
 which shall grow more rather than less, stronger rather than 
 weaker. 
 
 Economics treats of Man as in Process of Development. Few 
 truths are more easily admitted or more persistently ignored than 
 that of change in human life and condition. History makes it 
 real. Man now wanders about by force of necessity and age-long 
 habit, now starves rather than be moved from his home. Land 
 is now free to all, now parceled out with well-nigh absolute right 
 of individual possession. The seemingly eternal features of the 
 social structure are gone in a few generations. Nothing so invali- 
 dates theories, laws, general principles, institutions, and enter- 
 prises as this great law of change of which we seldom take full 
 account. Take, for instance, bequests. Nothing is commoner 
 than for a man to leave a legacy under specified and detailed 
 regulations, binding for all time. One leaves money to endow a 
 religious service in a language which in a few generations no one
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 7 
 
 understands; another founds a college to teach certain doctrines 
 which in a century no one believes; and so on indefinitely. These 
 and a thousand other laborious efforts of statesman, warrior, or 
 philosopher quite lose their worth for the future because their 
 authors assumed that the future would be like their present. Even 
 the wages system and the division between capital and labor which 
 seem rooted in the constitution of society are scarcely two centu- 
 ries old as a general system. One must never forget in the study 
 of economics that the phenomena with which it deals are per- 
 vaded by the spirit of life, moving forward or backward, pro- 
 gressing or decaying, under those influences which control the rise 
 and fall of social institutions. The science is biological rather 
 than mechanical. 
 
 The Laws with which Economics Deals. The evolutionary 
 character and complexity of economic phenomena, which account 
 for much of the charm of the subject, endow it also with unusual 
 difficulties. Conclusions true for one generation are invalid in 
 the next. Terms and definitions appropriate to one stage of in- 
 dustry are misleading in a succeeding stage. Generalizations valid 
 for one nation and government are inapplicable to another. Even 
 those laws or uniformities which the science prizes as the finest 
 product of its research are but statements of probabilities dec- 
 larations of what is most likely to occur for the mass of men in 
 the long run under certain specified circumstances. 
 
 In no department of knowledge, consequently, is there greater need of 
 temperate statement and of that humility of mind which is the surest safe- 
 guard against bigotry and dogmatism. No system of economics is appli- 
 cable unchanged to all times and all places : the premises of the arguments 
 change ; the ingredients of nearly every problem present themselves in differ- 
 ent proportions; and the conditions of almost every question vary from 
 country to country and from generation to generation. The student must not 
 expect rules of thumb by which he can decide offhand the economic problems 
 of the particular city or country district in which he is for the moment inter- 
 ested. No general treatise on economics can authoritatively decide the 
 practical problems of particular times and places; although the economist, 
 before all other students, is forced to deal with practical problems. What 
 such a treatise can do is to point out mistakes of logic common in the current 
 discussions of economic questions, call attention to obscure factors some- 
 times of great importance which the practical man is likely to overlook,
 
 8 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 give solutions of typical problems which are likely to arise, and thus afford a 
 training which will assist the student in solving practical problems for himself. 
 The peculiar and distinctive office of the economic scientist, however, is 
 to emphasize the less tangible truths, the remoter consequences, the deeper 
 and consequently less obvious forces of economic society. The impulses 
 of the moment, the immediate demands of the hour, the present "fact" that 
 stares us in the face (and sometimes blinds us), are not likely to lack vigorous 
 champions ; and to preserve the balance there is need of a craft of thinkers 
 far enough removed from the battle to preserve the wider outlook, mindful 
 of the lessons of the past, jealous for the rights of the future, insistent upon 
 the less obvious truths. This is why economics so frequently appears to 
 the practical man strained and academic. This impression arises from a 
 difference of emphasis which in the main is as salutary as it is inevitable. 
 The academic quality of the economist's work arises sometimes from igno- 
 rance, sometimes from pedantry, but more frequently from his courageous 
 insistence upon the importance of the less tangible truths and the distant 
 consequences of present action. 
 
 Is not economics, then, a science based upon natural law ? The 
 question is largely a verbal one. What do we mean by natural 
 law? In the narrowest sense natural laws are the habits of na- 
 ture which know absolutely no variation. Such are gravitation 
 and chemical affinity; and the sciences based upon such laws 
 astronomy, physics, and chemistry were the first to develop, 
 and have attained a maximum degree of exactitude. The term 
 " science " is sometimes used in a way to imply only sciences of 
 this character. These sciences are more properly known as 
 exact sciences, and they are characterized by the fact that the 
 relations with which they deal can usually be expressed quanti- 
 tatively. 
 
 When we come in contact with life, however, and especially 
 with its higher forms, the exactness with which an astronomer 
 predicts an eclipse or a chemist anticipates a reaction becomes 
 impossible. Not that life is without laws; very far from it. There 
 is, in the first place, the basis of physical nature, with its perfect 
 regularity, upon which all life rests and to which it must conform. 
 Then, too, there are laws governing life directly and pertaining to 
 it. These form the subject of the group of sciences known as 
 biology. We must remember, however, that all we can say of 
 natural laws is that they are habits, not compulsory necessities of
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 9 
 
 nature, and the laws of life seem to differ from those of inanimate 
 nature in that they are not quite invariable habits. Variability 
 seems to be inherent in life, increasing as life rises in the scale of 
 development. It is often assumed, to be sure, that these laws are 
 as invariable as any other, and that this seeming variability is 
 only a greater complexity which we do not yet understand. How- 
 ever that may be, the result is the same for the present. The sci- 
 ences of life are not exact in the sense we have defined. We must 
 further note that in so far as a science deals with facts which seem 
 to be governed by no invariable law, or whose law has not been 
 discovered, it must content itself with a description of this part 
 of its subject. Thus we have the term " descriptive science." We 
 might better speak of the descriptive part of a science, for all 
 sciences are able in part to reduce their facts to law. 
 
 What has been said of the sciences dealing with life applies to 
 an even greater extent to those sciences which deal with man. It 
 is perfectly true, of course, that within certain limits man is gov- 
 erned by absolutely invariable laws. He is as much bound by 
 gravitation as anything else, and if he falls over a precipice, we 
 can predict the results as certainly as though a stone fell over. 
 But, without entering the bog of discussion as to the nature of 
 human freedom, we may safely assume, for practical purposes, 
 that man is also, within certain limits, a law unto himself. No- 
 where do we find an element of variability so great and so seem- 
 ingly ultimate as here. We must remember, therefore, that the 
 sciences which deal with man deal with a being who is modified 
 by his environment, but who has the power of modifying that envi- 
 ronment by his own conscious effort. 
 
 Let us consider very carefully what this means. It does not 
 mean simply that man modifies his environment because he has 
 been modified by it and so reacts upon it, just as things do when 
 they come in contact. If we accept this view, we shall come to 
 Herbert Spencer's theory of natural selection. The forces at work 
 accomplish their own results, according to this theory, whether 
 man will or will not, simply by natural action and reaction. This 
 implies that man is modified by his environment, and that he in 
 turn modifies that environment without conscious effort. This
 
 10 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 theory is based on an assumption that man has no power of initi- 
 ating an influence, and consistently concludes that social develop- 
 ment, like geological development, must be left to work itself out. 
 Mr. Spencer, however, goes farther, and stoutly maintains that 
 man, by conscious effort, especially by collective or state effort, 
 not only does not help this development, but actually hinders it. 
 In this the whole theory is abandoned, for it is plain that if man 
 by conscious effort can hinder a process, he can help that process 
 in the same way, if he only has enough wisdom and sense. These 
 it is the purpose of science to give him. 
 
 In opposition to the theory of natural selection, or unconscious 
 development, has been urged the theory of artificial selection, or 
 conscious development. Ages of natural selection made of the 
 potato a lean, watery, unpalatable tuber; a few years of artificial 
 selection made it a valuable food product and a table delicacy. 
 Compare the development of domestic animals in the last few 
 years, under man's conscious guidance, with then- slow and meager 
 development in a state of nature. Man has precisely this power 
 of consciously modifying the natural and artificial elements of his 
 environment, and this power continually enlarges. 
 
 So, when we ask if economics deals with natural laws, we really 
 ask whether this being, whose activity in a certain line we are 
 studying, is governed by such laws. It we mean by this to ask 
 whether his action is characterized by absolutely invariable hab- 
 its, like the forces of physics, we must plainly answer, no. If 
 man had no power of initiative, or, on the other hand, were so 
 perfectly rational as to always do the wisest thing, there would be 
 a regularity in his action which might perhaps form the basis of 
 a complicated, but exact, science. As it is, all social sciences are 
 approximate and partly descriptive. There is much in man's ac- 
 tion which is exceedingly (though not perfectly) regular, and hence 
 we have general, though apparently not invariable, laws. There 
 is a part of his action, however, that seems as yet to be capricious, 
 and we can only make note of it till we have more knowledge. 
 
 The laws of economics are not comparable to the laws of inani- 
 mate nature in invariability, but they are of very general applica- 
 bility, and are wholly in line with the action and intent of nature,
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS II 
 
 and are, in this sense, "natural." But the laws of economics are 
 not natural laws in the sense in which the word is often used; 
 namely, laws external to man and not at all the product of man. 
 The laws of economics have been designated as social laws to 
 distinguish them from those of physical science. Social laws de- 
 scribe tendencies, or regularities, which appear especially in the 
 consideration of large masses of facts. Human mortality serves 
 as an illustration. When and how a certain man, as A, will die, 
 is proverbially uncertain; but when we speak of hundreds of thou- 
 sands of lives, we can predict with such an approximation of accu- 
 racy that a vast business-like life insurance can be built upon 
 the regularity of the action of death. 
 
 The foregoing discussion enables us to answer in a word the 
 much-mooted question, "Is economics a science?" It is not an 
 exact or mathematical science, though certain portions of the sub- 
 ject may possibly become so. It is an approximate and partially 
 descriptive science, like all sciences dealing with man, or even 
 with life. The inexactness of the social sciences is due to the very 
 thing which gives them their supreme value, the nature of man 
 and the greatness of their subject. 
 
 The Relation of Economics to other Sciences. We have al- 
 ready referred briefly to the relations between economics and some 
 of the other sciences, but the topic is one which requires fuller 
 treatment. In one sense, economics may be said to be dependent 
 upon practically every other science, since the discoveries in every 
 field of knowledge almost inevitably react upon the industrial life 
 of man. Modern chemistry, to take a single example, has revo- 
 lutionized some industries, wholly created others, and, through 
 the agency of the pure food laws, may claim most of the credit 
 for entirely suppressing others. From psychology economics takes 
 the axiomatic principles upon which the laws of value rest; from 
 physical science the law of diminishing returns which plays such 
 an important part in the theory of distribution; and from mathe- 
 matics the methods by which to ascertain how insurance may be 
 safely supplied against accidents, death, and loss by fire. But 
 it is to the sister sciences dealing primarily with man that eco- 
 nomics is most vitallv related.
 
 12 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Man has been busy from the first in several lines of effort. He 
 has talked, worshiped, fought, studied, and each of these lines 
 of effort has developed its own faculties and institutions. For 
 convenience we may arrange these in eight groups, as follows: 
 language, art, education, religion, family life, society life, politi- 
 cal life, economic life. Each of these is the subject of a science 
 more or less developed. The group of society life that is, the 
 life of polite society, calls, parties, balls, and the like has been 
 studied but little, and we know few of its governing principles. 1 
 Language, on the other hand, is a science which has attained to 
 very complete development. The rest lie scattered between these 
 extremes. 
 
 A peculiar feature of these activities is that they are all of them 
 collective activities, activities which one man cannot well carry on 
 alone. This is obviously true of family and political life, language, 
 and others, and on careful examination it proves to be true of 
 the rest. It is now admitted, after many experiments, that art 
 and even religion do not thrive in solitude. It would seem that 
 if a man could do anything by himself, it would be to get a living; 
 but our brief study of history impresses us with the insignificance 
 of all such effort and the inevitable tendency of men to drift to- 
 gether in their economic activity. If it were possible for men to 
 live in isolation, every one of the eight lines of effort we have men- 
 tioned would soon dwindle into insignificance or altogether cease. 
 So these sciences are all of them social sciences; and as the sci- 
 ences that deal with life are now grouped together under the name 
 biology (science of life), so the social sciences are grouped under 
 the title of sociology, or the science of society, although some 
 sociologists do not define the word "sociology" in this broad sense 
 of an all-embracing science of human association. 
 
 Economics, then, is a branch of sociology. We have already 
 defined it as the science which treats of those social phenomena 
 that are due to the wealth-getting and wealth-using activities of 
 man. We may speak of the wealth-getting and wealth-using 
 
 1 An attempt to examine scientifically some, at least, of the phenomena of 
 polite society has been made by a learned jurist, the late Professor Rudolph von 
 Ihcring, in his Zweck im Rtcht. Cf. also Veblen, The Theory of the Leisure Class.
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 13 
 
 activities in all their relations as economic life or economy. Ac- 
 cordingly, economics is the science which deals with the economy 
 of man. A useful distinction in language is thus made between 
 economy, the life itself, and economics, the science dealing with 
 that life. If this distinction could always be observed, much con- 
 fusion would be avoided. 
 
 We have economies of various sorts: the economy of an indi- 
 vidual, of a family, a tribe, a city, a state, or a nation, and we 
 have, correspondingly, many economic units. The dominant unit 
 in ancient Greece, for example, was the household, which included 
 the family and all the slaves and other dependents. These lived 
 together and formed a little group by themselves. The economic 
 life of Greece meant, largely, a sum of the economic activities of 
 these households, each of which strove to be sufficient unto itself. 
 It is interesting to know that many a well-managed Southern 
 plantation before the late Civil War endeavored to produce all the 
 means of life on the plantation, and in this respect, as in others, 
 resembled a Greek household. But as time has progressed, these 
 old groups have been partially dissolved, and in many instances 
 in modern times the individual, in his economic activity, consti- 
 tutes a unit, although the family is still the prevalent economic 
 unit. It is a natural outcome of industrial progress, as already 
 explained, that the relations between these units have multiplied 
 indefinitely in number and in importance. This is simply another 
 way of describing the growing interdependence of men. Eco- 
 nomics deals especially with the mutual relations of economies of 
 all kinds, private and public. It is chiefly, if not exclusively, a 
 science of human relations, and without these relations could not 
 exist. 
 
 Because of the organic connection of these relations in their 
 common origin, man, and because economics deals with the indi- 
 vidual as he is, and not with an artificially simplified "economic 
 man," it is impossible wholly to dissociate the social sciences, 
 and particularly impossible to divorce economics completely from 
 ethics and politics. This does not mean that these sciences are 
 all one and cannot be profitably subdivided. On the contrary, 
 because of the limitations of the human mind, they must be
 
 14 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 studied separately so far as is possible. Scientific progress, like 
 industrial progress, comes largely through specialization and the 
 division of labor. Man cannot profitably study things in general. 
 What it does mean is that there is some territory common to all 
 these sciences, and that occasionally the economist is forced to 
 pass ethical judgment and to decide political questions. In the 
 consideration of railway rates, for instance, the economist is not 
 only compelled to pass judgment upon what is just and reasonable, 
 but he discovers upon investigation that by common consent what 
 is fair or reasonable is decided largely upon economic grounds. 
 The same is true of the apportionment of taxes, in which subject 
 ethical, legal, and economic questions are inextricably interwoven. 
 Commercial policies, restrictive regulations, and sumptuary laws 
 have been the very stuff and subject-matter of the science of eco- 
 nomics from its very beginning. In analyzing the progress of 
 the past or the conditions of the present, we are forced to pass 
 judgment upon the success or failure of many laws and policies 
 which are still in force or under active discussion. Many of these 
 must be indorsed or repudiated either solely or largely upon 
 economic grounds; and because of these facts, the economist can- 
 not, even if he would, refrain from passing judgment upon laws 
 and political policies. Nevertheless, as was stated before, eco- 
 nomics does not undertake the complete and systematic study of 
 law, ethics, and politics, and its conclusions must almost always 
 be supplemented by non -economic considerations which the 
 economist may not have taken into account. 
 
 In the preface to the first edition of his Principles of Economics, Professor 
 Marshall seems to dissent from the views here expressed, maintaining that 
 " the laws of economics are statements of tendencies expressed in the indica- 
 tive mode and not ethical precepts in the imperative." But even this most 
 cautious and consistent of economists cannot refrain from laying down 
 ethical precepts in many parts of his work. On almost the very last page 
 he declares that : " The most imperative duty of this generation is to provide 
 for the young such opportunities as will both develop their higher nature, and 
 make them efficient producers. And an essential condition to this end is 
 long-continued freedom from mechanical toil ; together with abundant 
 leisure for school and for such kinds of play as strengthen and develop the 
 character." * 
 
 1 Marshall, Principles of Economics, 5th ed., p. 720.
 
 THE NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS 15 
 
 Principal Divisions of Economics. This view of the inevitably 
 practical character of economic science is carried out in the treat- 
 ment of the subject in the following pages. The history and evo- 
 lution of economic society, sketched in Book I, are followed, in 
 Book II, by a discussion of the consumption, production, exchange 
 and distribution of wealth. These subjects are treated in close 
 connection with those illustrative economic problems of which 
 the so-called ''economic theory," at its best, is but a more com- 
 prehensive and consequently more abstract analysis. Book III 
 has been reserved for the subject of public finance, which, in the 
 opinion of the authors, constitutes as integral a part of economic 
 science as the subjects of money or international trade. In Book 
 IV is given a brief sketch of the history of economic thought. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. What is the most essential characteristic of economics? Define eco- 
 nomics. 
 
 2. Is man or goods the more prominent thing in economic study? Does 
 economics teach the student how to get rich ? 
 
 3. What determines ultimately whether a man is poor or not? What 
 kinds of poverty are there ? 
 
 4. What is meant by "dear labor"? Is it a good thing for society in 
 general? for employers in general? for an individual employer? 
 
 5. What is the difference between natural and artificial selection? Which 
 applies to human society ? 
 
 6. Are practical ethical and political judgments the chief ends and prod- 
 ucts of economic science ? 
 
 7. Is economics concerned with the negro question? asset currency? 
 prohibition? anti-trust laws? race suicide? protection? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CAIRNES, J. E. The Character and Logical Method of Political Economy. 
 COSSA, L. An Introduction to the Study of Political Economy. 
 INGRAM, J. K. .4 History of Political Economy. Chap. VII. 
 KEYNES, J. The Scope and Method of Political Economy. 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 5th ed., Appendix C. 
 MILL, J. S. Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy. 
 SIDGWICK, HENRY. The Scope and Method of Economic Science. 
 WAGXER, A. " On the Present State of Political Economy." Quarterly 
 Journal of Economics, Vol. I.
 
 CHAPTER II 
 
 THE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE PRESENT ECONOMIC 
 
 SYSTEM 
 
 IT is the object of the present chapter to give a descriptive 
 survey of the fundamental institutions and forces of the existing 
 economic order. 
 
 Our Environment. Lying back of all of our economic activity 
 is the fact that we live in an environment in which the things that 
 we desire are not furnished spontaneously in unlimited quantities. 
 Whether it be looked upon as due to the niggardliness of nature 
 or to the insatiability of human wants, the fact is that, for the most 
 part, the material things that we use must be economized. We 
 must put forth effort and exercise self-denial in order to enjoy 
 the good things of life. Those human arrangements which help 
 to determine how much of effort, of self-denial, and of enjoyment 
 is to fall to the lot of each of us are the characteristics to which 
 we now turn our attention. There are, however, a number of 
 social institutions which do not fall within the scope of the pres- 
 ent chapter. We deal here only with the social conditions directly 
 underlying our economic activity, which is but one aspect of our 
 social life. We must leave to the sociologists and other students 
 of society a discussion of such topics as the family, religion, mo- 
 rality, ceremonial institutions, and the nature of government, 
 although, to be sure, these also have their effect upon the 
 economic sphere and are in turn affected by it. In the present 
 chapter also we omit a study of the economic significance of our 
 physical environment, which receives independent treatment in 
 books on economic geography. 
 
 Private Enterprise and State Activity. We live in an age when 
 private enterprise, for the most part, is relied upon to furnish us 
 
 16
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 17 
 
 with the necessities and enjoyments of life. The cultivation of 
 the soil, the exploitation of the mines, transportation, the various 
 stages of manufacture, and the distribution of the finished prod- 
 uct are all left mainly 1 to private initiative. The discovery of 
 new processes, invention, and experimentation are carried on 
 mostly by private individuals or corporations who take upon their 
 own shoulders the risk of failure. The State, on the other hand, 
 participates in this activity in a variety of ways. It maintains 
 order, promotes the public health and safety, provides roads, and 
 takes charge of some industries completely. In its educational 
 institutions the State, through its agents, undertakes various ex- 
 periments, and encourages the growth and diffusion of knowl- 
 edge, an indispensable condition of continuous advancement of 
 our economic life. The state university and the experiment farms 
 may be mentioned, and also the large and extremely useful De- 
 partment of Agriculture of the United States, with its annual 
 expenditure now exceeding six million dollars. Certainly in the 
 vast majority of the enterprises with which we are familiar, pri- 
 vate and public activities are combined in varying proportions. 
 
 Let us take the case of an industry which is as nearly private, 
 perhaps, as any we can find, that of agriculture, and notice 
 the part which public activities play in securing the farmer's re- 
 sult. First, we may say that the farmer owns the farm that he 
 cultivates; this is private property. But how comes it that the 
 farm is his? Why does not a stronger man drive him off and 
 take the farm himself ? Plainly because the State protects him in 
 the possession of the farm. When he bought the farm, he took 
 his deed to a government official, who recorded it, and thus gave 
 him an additional guarantee of possession. A neighbor's dog 
 kills his sheep, and an appeal to the State compels the neighbor 
 to redress the grievance. Another, far below, dams a river and 
 backs the water up so that it overflows his land. Another appeal 
 to the State removes the dam or secures compensation. When 
 wheat is raised, the farmer hauls it to market by a road built, not 
 by private, but by public, activity. The railway lowers the price 
 
 1 This applies especially to the United States and England so far as transpor- 
 tation is concerned ; it would scarcely hold true of the world as a whole. 
 C
 
 l8 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of his wheat by a discriminating rate, and again government in- 
 terferes in his behalf. But manifold and important as are the 
 regulations of the government, State activity seems very much 
 restricted when we reflect that it might extend over the entire 
 industrial field. To-day the distinctive characteristic of our eco- 
 nomic life is private, not public, enterprise. 
 
 Division of Labor and Exchange. It is commonly taken for 
 granted that every man should prepare himself for some special 
 occupation, that one should plow while another builds or sings. 
 Hardly any civilization seems possible without some industrial 
 specialization, but our own age is peculiar on account of the ex- 
 tent to which this has been carried. The introduction of machin- 
 ery and the development of large-scale production have split up 
 so minutely the work of men that the products which they turn 
 out are not only not of immediate use to themselves in most cases, 
 but they are also useless to any one else until combined with the 
 results of other men's labor, often performed years before or after- 
 wards. It is a long and complicated process from the man who 
 mines the ore which is to reappear in a steel plow, to the man who 
 bakes the bread. The effects of this specialization of employ- 
 ment are far-reaching : 
 
 (i) It implies the exchange of goods. If we produce things 
 we do not need, we must find some one else who does want them 
 and some one who has the things we desire. Money, banks, and 
 transportation agencies could largely be dispensed with if each 
 family produced for itself alone. There would be none of the 
 complex problems that center about the question of how much 
 each of us is to receive in exchange for his services. One of the 
 striking characteristics of this process of exchange is the great 
 extent to which it is automatic. There is no government official 
 whose business it is to discover how much of each commodity 
 will be needed, and to direct that that amount shall be produced. 1 
 Men are legally allowed to engage in almost any undertaking that 
 attracts them, and yet we take it for granted that somehow things 
 will get produced in the proper proportions. A hundred men are 
 
 1 The government does help, however, in collecting and publishing information, 
 as in the case of crop reports.
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 19 
 
 set to work in a factory making nothing but hats, many more 
 than they or their friends can use, but the manager has faith that 
 heads will be found to wear them all. Farmers confidently pro- 
 ceed to raise wheat, never troubling themselves about the grind- 
 ing and baking. Neither workmen nor employers in general 
 know why wages are as they are. Men lend money or goods, now 
 for one price, now for another, but few know why they demand 
 interest or why the rate changes. These processes go on visibly 
 before us, but the governing laws are hidden except to the care- 
 ful investigator. In this respect they are like the laws of physi- 
 ology. We eat and digest our food, but how many people know 
 how or why digestion takes place? It is easy, however, to over- 
 emphasize this idea, for a great deal of our economic activity is 
 conscious and volitional. When we decide to make a law or levy 
 a tax, we do it consciously, considering arguments, and finally 
 will the thing in question. Further, in the large business con- 
 solidations, much knowledge regarding the course of trade is 
 obtained directly through special agents or reports and is made 
 the basis of conscious action. 
 
 (2) Specialization of work and exchange of goods just referred 
 to, necessarily implies mutual dependence. Instead of a number 
 of distinct, self-sufficient units, we have a coherent society where 
 one individual relies upon many others to complete his own one- 
 sided economic activity. A strike of the street car employees, or 
 of the teamsters, or the destruction of an electric lighting plant, 
 would each send a shock of inconvenience through a community. 
 A prolonged railway strike would be felt as a national misfortune. 
 Indeed, this interdependence is international in its scope. Eng- 
 land relies on other nations to send her food in exchange for her 
 manufactured products, and many a German workman would be 
 in distress if there should be a sudden failure in our cotton crop. 
 
 Economic Classes. In part, also, the specialization of work is 
 responsible for the division of society into classes, but only in 
 part. The difference in the work of the carpenter, machinist, or 
 railway brakeman does not result in the formation of classes of a 
 higher and lower rank. On the other hand, the professional brain 
 worker enjoys some social esteem that does not fall to the lot of
 
 20 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the manual worker. But doubtless the most important basis of 
 social classification is the possession of wealth. The power to 
 spend freely, while not the only test, is to-day the most widely rec- 
 ognized test of social status, regret it as we may. 
 
 Private Property. We proceed now to examine the founda- 
 tion stones of this system of private enterprise. Private property 
 is the most important of these. 
 
 The leading English writers of economic treatises have usually taken the 
 institution of private property as something to be assumed as a starting 
 point in their discussions. John Stuart Mill, indeed, made an excellent 
 beginning in the discussion of property and inheritance in his Principles of 
 Political Economy, but other English writers have not generally followed 
 up his lead. It is to the merit of the German writers that they have critic- 
 ally examined these fundamental institutions in their economic bearings. 
 The work of Professor Adolph Wagner may be mentioned especially in this 
 connection. 
 
 For our present purpose we may define private property as. the 
 exclusive control over valuable things by private persons. It is 
 to be distinguished from mere possession. The possessor has the 
 use of the thing for the time being, but unless he is at the same 
 time the owner, he is dependent upon the will of another for the 
 use of it. Ownership implies the right of excluding other per- 
 sons from the enjoyment of a thing. The exclusive right must 
 be recognized and guaranteed effectively by third parties. If I 
 defend my exclusive right of control over some valuable thing 
 against your claim simply by the strength of my right arm, I have 
 not thereby established the right of private property. My ex- 
 clusive right of control must be recognized by others and must 
 be maintained by them. Over against private property we have 
 public property, and there are some things, such as air, which 
 fall in neither of these categories. The sphere of private property 
 at present includes, not only food, clothes, and other things of 
 personal use, but it also includes the instruments of production 
 land, buildings, and machinery. In the most important pro- 
 ductive processes the tools are in general not owned by the per- 
 sons who use them. Hence our present wage system. 
 
 It may be said that property is the chief seat of social authority. As 
 property carries with it the exclusive right to control things, others may have
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 21 
 
 access to these things only on conditions named by their owners. If 
 we look about us, we find men organized and acting together under 
 direction for purposes of production. In a factory we find an organization 
 of men like that of an army. We discover men moving here and there and 
 performing arduous tasks in obedience to command. If we examine the 
 nature of the authority which some thus exercise over others, we shall find 
 that it resides in property. The law of the land to some extent establishes 
 the authority of man over man ; but where one man obeys another because 
 the law in so many words tells him to do so, we find a hundred men obeying 
 others because these others have the authority which resides in exclusive 
 control over valuable things. Indirectly this latter sort of authority rests 
 back upon the laws in so far as these are responsible for the establishment of 
 property. But the chief seat of authority in society is based only indirectly 
 upon the government ; it rests immediately upon private property. 
 
 Inheritance. Inheritance is often regarded as a necessary part 
 of the right of private property, and it is true that the entire abo- 
 lition of the right of inheritance would result in a great enlarge- 
 ment of the public sphere of property at the expense of the private 
 sphere, unless gifts were made to accomplish the same object as 
 the system of inheritance. But strictly speaking, we have here to 
 do with two rights. Private property is an exclusive right of con- 
 trol, whereas inheritance is concerned with the transmission of 
 this right from one generation to another. 
 
 As in the case of private property itself, the right of inheritance 
 is not recognized to-day as an absolute one. Detailed regulations 
 exist on our statute books regarding the descent of property where 
 no will is made, and also regarding the making of wills, and there 
 is an increasing tendency to limit the right of inheritance by taxa- 
 tion. Some features of the present law of inheritance well illus- 
 trate the tendency of institutions to persist after the conditions 
 that gave rise to them have disappeared. The recognition which 
 we give to the claims of very distant relatives to a share in an 
 estate where there are no near relatives, and where no will has 
 been made, had its origin at a time when blood relationship played 
 a much more important part in society than it does at present. 
 
 Contract. Scarcely second to the right of private property is 
 the right of contract, for the maintenance of which we are equally 
 dependent on the State. Some sort of contract lies at the basis 
 of all associated activity. To secure the condition of such activity,
 
 22 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 it is necessary, first, that men should be allowed to bind them- 
 selves; and second, that they should be compelled to respect the 
 agreement thus entered into. The entrance into a valid contract 
 is ordinarily voluntary, but once entered into with due formality, 
 the State will use its superior power to enforce it. To the anar- 
 chistic mind this seems oppressive, and it must be admitted that 
 a state of society is conceivable in which the element of force 
 would be removed from the idea of contract, but something else 
 would have to be substituted to make the keeping of agreements 
 the general rule. There are doubtless many people living to-day 
 with whom the feeling of honor or fear of social disapprobation 
 would be sufficient for the enforcement of contracts, just as these 
 persons might not need the threat of a jail sentence to keep them 
 from stealing. 
 
 The economic ties which hold men together in industrial society on their 
 legal side are very generally contracts. The organization of an industrial 
 corporation implies many contracts. Our property is acquired very largely 
 through contract, and through contract we determine the conditions under 
 which we do our work, such as the length of the working day. The conti- 
 nuity of our economic life rests upon contracts, which bind together past, 
 present, and future. Still, all that we have by no means comes to us through 
 contract. "Contract" does not exhaust the significance of parentage, home, 
 and education, and much wealth changes hands through gifts and inheritance. 
 
 Vested Interests. 1 A few words should be said about vested 
 interests. Vested interests may be denned as pecuniary interests 
 which are legally recognized to be such that they cannot be im- 
 paired by public action without indemnification. Vested inter- 
 ests generally arise through property and contract. Outside of 
 property and contract, however, there may be vested interests. 
 Leeds was compelled by a feudal arrangement to grind its corn, 
 grain, and meal at the lord's mill till well on in the last cen- 
 tury, and finally had to pay 1 3,000 to terminate this obligation. 
 When Prussia bought the railways, the railway presidents were 
 indemnified for the loss of their positions by large payments; in 
 other words, their offices were looked upon as vested interests. 
 England is the classic land of vested interests. An office in the 
 army was until recently looked upon as such, and so was an 
 
 'The term " vested rights " is also used.
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 23 
 
 appointment in the Established Church. It is generally held that 
 saloon keepers in England have a vested interest in their busi- 
 ness, so that they must be indemnified if their licenses are taken 
 from them. Workingmen have frequently claimed that they have 
 a vested interest in the advantages which their acquired skill gives 
 them, and consequently that if through industrial changes this 
 skill ceases to be of as great value as formerly, they ought to be 
 indemnified and in some way their former income continued. 
 This claim of the workingmen, however, unlike many other claims 
 put forward in the name of vested interests, has not received rec- 
 ognition, either by Parliament or the courts. Vested interests, 
 apart from property and contract, are of less significance in the 
 United States than in most countries, but they may become of 
 more significance in the future. 
 
 Freedom. The words " liberty " and " freedom " have given rise 
 to some of the deepest philosophical discussions, but we may avoid 
 confusion if we say that the freedom to do certain things is legally 
 guaranteed at the present time, such as moving from one part 
 of the country to another, choosing one's own occupation, and 
 acquiring property. These, together with the absence of chattel 
 slavery and imprisonment for debt, are characteristic features of 
 the present economic order as distinguished from past conditions. 
 The right to manufacture and sell what and when one pleases is a 
 comparatively recent one. It has often been greatly limited by 
 despotic governments, and the right has been made a matter of 
 sale for the purpose of raising revenue. Most such limitations 
 have been of the nature of abuses, and our own time has seen the 
 abolition of an immense number of hampering and vexatious re- 
 strictions designed for plunder rather than for the promotion of 
 private enterprise. So far as the absence of legal restrictions on 
 the actions of individuals is concerned, the past century has been 
 distinctively an age of liberty. 
 
 Restrictive laws, however, are not the only limitations on our 
 freedom of action. The system of private property itself means 
 that certain individuals in the community have power to command 
 other people to work, and the lack of an income under our present 
 regime implies the lack of the real freedom to do things. The
 
 24 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 cost of a railway ticket may be quite as effective as a legal barrier 
 would be in preventing movement from one state to another. It 
 is said that we are free to acquire unlimited property. True, the 
 law does not expressly prohibit such acquisition, but as a matter 
 of fact many persons do not acquire much property. Again, we 
 say involuntary servitude, except as punishment for crime, has been 
 abolished, yet men are compelled to work by the threat of eco- 
 nomic distress, in most cases quite as effectively as by means of 
 the slave-driver's whip, for the counterpart of legal freedom is 
 the economic responsibility of the individual. "Sink or swim," 
 says the State to the millions struggling for worldly goods. That 
 is the end of the matter according to the laissez-faire theory. The 
 modern State helps men to learn to swim. Again, the choice of an 
 occupation is free according to the law, but we may find that a 
 long and expensive course of training is necessary, or we may be 
 compelled to conform to trades-union regulations, and always it is 
 necessary to find some one who deems our services valuable. The 
 right to establish enterprises is granted to all alike according to 
 the law, but to-day it would be difficult and hazardous to embark 
 upon the refining of oil or the manufacture of steel. Practically, 
 the freedom to establish new enterprises has been growing less 
 and less in this era of large-scale production. 
 
 Competition and Markets. As a result of the legal conditions 
 that have been mentioned, we find men engaged in many kinds 
 of rivalry. Our economic society is often called "competitive" 
 for this reason. But when this term is used, not all forms of 
 rivalry are meant, for even if private property and free contract 
 were abolished, some form of struggle might still persist. There 
 might still be conflicts between races and nations, and the men of 
 any single nation might still vie with one another to prove their 
 superiority in the eyes of womankind or to gain positions of pub- 
 lic honor and power. The kind of competition which is distinc- 
 tive of the present economic order is the all-pervading endeavor 
 to obtain the largest possible amount of wealth in exchange for 
 commodities produced or services rendered. If we except the 
 idlers, the parasites, and the cheaters, men are everywhere en- 
 deavoring to discover what other people want urgently, and then
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 25 
 
 to satisfy that want in the most efficient manner possible. On the 
 other hand, they attempt to give as little as possible of their own 
 products in exchange for the things they themselves desire. Busi- 
 ness competition thus has two sides: rivalry in rendering a serv- 
 ice, and alertness in exacting a return. Each individual takes 
 part in the competitive contest in two ways: first, as a seller of 
 goods or services, in which case he finds that others are anxious 
 to render the same service; and second, as a buyer of the things 
 he wants, in which case he finds that these same things are sought 
 after by other people. 
 
 The intensity of the competitive struggle is subject to a good 
 deal of variation. At times it may be characterized as cut-throat, 
 where the slashing of prices has for its object the elimination of 
 one or more of the contestants. But the rivalry is not necessarily 
 so fierce. In some lines of business many competitors may con- 
 tinue to exist side by side indefinitely, each competitor being con- 
 fronted by the ever present threat that if his service becomes very 
 poor, some other man will outstrip him. Various as may be the 
 character of competition, now predator)', now a friendly rivalry, 
 there is no resting place in the contest unless one secures some 
 special privilege as a shelter. He who is energetic, and wins suc- 
 cess in a certain line of business, must continue to defend himself 
 from a host of imitators who are anxious to snatch his gains from 
 him. Most of the competitors are successful in getting something, 
 some more than others, but many fail altogether. These last, the 
 inefficient, whether made so by sickness, by inherited weakness, 
 or by lack of proper training, fall by the wayside and must be cared 
 for by private charity or by the State. The process is cruel in 
 many of its details, but there is also a beneficent aspect in the 
 sifting out of the incompetent and in the encouragement of the 
 strong. 
 
 Here, again, reference may be made to the automatic character 
 of the present industrial system. It is through competition and 
 bargaining in the market that a price is fixed, and it is to the vari- 
 ations in this price that business men look for indications as to 
 what people want rather than to the reports of some government 
 official, although such reports are of some assistance. Price is
 
 26 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the universal barometer that indicates changes in the demand for 
 goods of all kinds. 
 
 Competition has been spoken of as a struggle, a contest, ac- 
 companied by success and failure, elation and disappointment. 
 But the State sets limits to the rivalry it makes regulations and 
 acts as an umpire to compel fair play. It attempts to eliminate 
 fraud and brute force; it trains the rising generations for an en- 
 trance into the struggle by a system of free education; it insists 
 that no person shall sacrifice the life and limb of another in the 
 rush for wealth; and it protects children and women when they 
 seem compelled to labor under unhealthful conditions. Those who 
 fail entirely in the struggle it tries to rescue from suffering. In 
 short, the State, as will be explained more fully in a later chap- 
 ter, aims to raise the plane of competition, changing it from bru- 
 tal warfare into a contest in which there are prizes for all, but in 
 which the prizes are graded according to the energy and ability 
 of the contestants. 
 
 Cooperation. The statement that our age is one of competi- 
 tion is misleading if it gives the impression that every individual 
 is continually struggling against all of his fellows. On the con- 
 trary, the achievements of modern industrial civilization would be 
 impossible without a far-reaching cooperation between individ- 
 uals. Employers and employees may quarrel and bargain about 
 the wage contract, but when they have settled their relations for a 
 week or a year, they become cooperators during that period in 
 the conduct of the business enterprise in which they are engaged. 
 Again, there is an unconscious cooperation between those who 
 work upon a commodity in the different stages of the process from 
 raw material to finished product. The division of labor itself 
 necessarily implies cooperation. Competition merely determines 
 the conditions on which the cooperation takes place. If these 
 conditions could be determined in some other manner, it would 
 be possible to conceive of the elimination of competition from our 
 industrial system, but cooperation is so vital and fundamental 
 that its elimination would mean a return to barbarism. 
 
 Monopoly. Everywhere in the industrial field the tendency 
 toward monopoly is present. Business men endeavor so far as
 
 THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM 27 
 
 possible to shelter themselves from the effects of the competitive 
 struggle by means of some privilege, but if none is to be found, 
 and if competition becomes very keen, they endeavor to combine 
 with other business men. But while this attempt to escape com- 
 petition is universal, it is only under certain conditions that it is 
 at all likely to succeed. The success is least in agriculture and in 
 the mercantile business, where new enterprises are started rather 
 easily because no special privileges stand in the way and because 
 no very large capital is required to work efficiently. It is greatest 
 in mining and transportation, where special privileges are present 
 and where large capital is required. Scarcely anywhere is it pos- 
 sible wholly to escape competition, and we are still warranted 
 in speaking of the present era as a competitive rather than a 
 monopolistic age. 
 
 Side by side with the growth of monopoly there is an increase 
 in government interference in industry. The desire of the busi- 
 ness man is to be uncontrolled, but wherever he succeeds in throw- 
 ing off the control exercised by his competitors, he inevitably 
 substitutes that of the government official. 
 
 Custom. Custom plays an important part in our economic 
 activity as well as in every other department of social life, although 
 its sway is not so marked as in former ages or among primitive 
 peoples. The custom of giving gratuities, or tip*, to servants is 
 in many places so strong as to have almost the force of law. Again, 
 to-day much of our personal expenditure is controlled by what 
 custom has declared to be proper rather than by any act of our 
 own individual reason. Any attempt to lower wages which would 
 make impossible the maintenance of a customary standard of liv- 
 ing would be stubbornly resisted. Custom is the result of habit, 
 and is continually broken into by our tendency to imitate a leader 
 who proposes a new line of action. Recent events in the spelling 
 reform movement afford an illustration. While custom may have 
 its beneficent aspect in preventing hasty and impulsive changes, 
 it frequently retards progress and causes our legislation and judi- 
 cial decisions to lag behind industrial development. 
 
 Authority and Benevolence. In the preceding pages frequent 
 reference was made to the limitations upon the rights of private
 
 28 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 property, inheritance, contract, and freedom. Public authority 
 may be looked upon as one of the forces governing the economic 
 process. The conduct of private enterprises is continually being 
 interfered with by State authority. Legal rates of interest are 
 established, and "reasonable" railway charges are substituted 
 for actual charges. The authoritative fixation of wages is a 
 future possibility. 
 
 Benevolence, or the caritative principle, may be mentioned as 
 another force in economic society, modifying and supplementing 
 in many ways the work of competition. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Attempt to classify the leading occupations in your city with respect 
 to the social prestige attaching to them. 
 
 2. Describe the property relations existing in the Amana Society, or in 
 other communistic groups. 
 
 3. What regulations concerning the inheritance of property are in force 
 in your state ? 
 
 4. To what extent are gambling contracts valid ? 
 
 5. Compare the legal freedom of workingmen to-day with the conditions 
 described in the Wealth of Nations, Book I, Chap. X, Part II. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BAKER, C. W. Monopolies and the People, Chaps. X and XI. 
 
 BLISS, W. D. P. Encyclopedia of Social Reform (new ed.), article on 
 
 Amana Community. See also on sample subject, Ely, R. T., in 
 
 Harper's Monthly Magazine, October, 1902. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Evolution of Industrial Society, Part II, Chaps. I, VII, or XI. 
 GREEN, T. H. Liberal Legislation and Freedom of Contract, Works, Vol. 
 
 Ill, p. 365. 
 
 MILL, J. S. On Liberty, Chap. IV. 
 
 MILL, J. S. Principles of Political Economy, Book II, Chaps. I and II. 
 NICHOLSON, J. SHIELD. Principles of Political Economy, Vol. I, Book II, 
 
 Chaps. II-VIII. 
 
 PATTEN, S. N. Development of English Thought, pp. 22-23. 
 STEPHENS, J. F. Liberty, Equality, and Fraternity. 
 
 SIDGWTCK, HENRY. Principles of Political Economy, Book II, Chap. XII. 
 WEBB, SIDNEY and BEATRICE. Industrial Democracy, Vol. II, pp. 562-572.
 
 CHAPTER III 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 
 
 IN the preceding chapter were described the fundamental insti- 
 tutions of the present economic order. Here a brief sketch will 
 be given of the origin and development of these institutions. Such 
 a study is advisable in a general survey of the field of political 
 economy because many of the problems and proposed reforms 
 which are met with raise questions as to the soundness of the 
 very foundations of our present economic life, and these can only 
 be understood when they are viewed as historical products. 
 
 The evolution of economic society is but one of many stand- 
 points from which the development of mankind may be consid- 
 ered. The history of literature, the history of government, the 
 history of religion, each treats of man in one line of his activities. 
 Many thinkers have considered the economic activities of man- 
 kind as the fundamental factor in social progress, determining in 
 the long run even our ethical and religious conceptions. Prob- 
 ably human life is too complex for any such simple explanation. 
 The economic factor, however, is clearly of the most fundamental 
 importance in the sense that the higher things in life cannot be 
 cultivated if man's entire time is spent in getting a mere subsist- 
 ence, so that economic progress, or gaining control over the forces 
 of nature, must accompany general social advancement, at least 
 for the mass of the community. Under primitive methods of 
 production, only a select few can have this leisure time. 
 
 The Economic Stages. Many attempts have been made to 
 divide economic history into stages through which mankind passed 
 in arriving at modern industrial civilization. These attempts have 
 been the subject of lively criticism, but it appears that the classifi- 
 cation which in the past has been most widely used is still, with 
 
 29
 
 30 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 some modifications, the most serviceable, and in the main, this 
 will be followed in the present chapter. 
 
 The basis of this classification is the increasing power of man 
 over nature. This is the fundamental fact in man's economic 
 development, and his position in the scale of economic civilization 
 is higher in proportion as this power over nature increases. In- 
 creasing control of nature is accompanied by changes in man 
 himself, especially by a growth and diversification in his wants, 
 so that we may say that economic civilization consists largely in 
 wanting many things and in learning how to make and use them. 
 From this standpoint economic history may be divided into the 
 following stages : 
 
 I. Direct Appropriation. 
 
 II. The Pastoral Stage. 
 
 III. The Agricultural Stage. 
 
 IV. The Handicraft Stage. 
 V. The Industrial Stage. 
 
 I. DIRECT APPROPRIATION 
 
 The economy of primitive man is characterized by finding things 
 ready to use instead of making them. It is not intended to assert 
 that the lowest examples of mankind that we know do absolutely 
 nothing in the way of transforming the materials of nature for 
 use. The lowest types know the use of fire and have rude tools, 
 but, nevertheless, the farther back we go, the more direct do we 
 find the reliance on nature. One cannot read descriptions of the 
 Negritos, Veddahs, Fuegians, or native Australians without being 
 impressed with the similarity between the economy of these peo- 
 ples and that of the lower animals. But there are many tribes 
 commonly regarded as savages that show a great advancement 
 over those that have been mentioned. Among the North Ameri- 
 can Indians, for example, we find a rude sort of cultivation of the 
 soil along with hunting and fishing. Such soil cultivation has 
 been termed " hoe-culture," and is to be distinguished from agri- 
 culture with the aid of domesticated animals found in a later stage 
 of development.
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 31 
 
 This kind of agriculture is found in its highest state of development among 
 the negroes of Africa. " The ground for cultivation," says Ratzel, " is cleared 
 by means of fire, or with the hatchet or small ax. On the east coast a broad 
 chopper with a spear-shaped blade and short handle is also used. The 
 lance or spearhead has, in general, to serve many peaceful purposes. Larger 
 trees are killed by barking. Thorny branches are placed as a border to the 
 fields, under the shelter of which close, quick hedges gradually grow up. The 
 ground is broken and cleared of weeds with a wooden spade sharpened to an 
 edge at either end. Many peoples have hitherto not ventured to use iron 
 tools, since they keep away the rain. When the ground has been got ready, 
 somewhere about the beginning of the rainy season, the sower walks over 
 the field, scraping a hole with his naked foot at every step, into which he lets 
 some grains fall from his hand ; the foot covers them up, and if the good 
 witch doctor makes rain enough, and the bad one does not keep it back, there 
 is nothing more to be done until harvest, unless to hoe the weeds once. . . . 
 To the present day the plow is practically strange to them." * 
 
 The following characterization of the economy of primitive man 
 applies with varying force to the many tribes that may be placed 
 in this first stage. 
 
 Characteristics of Primitive Man. The range of wants is nar- 
 row, as the savage is almost completely satisfied if he obtains mere 
 subsistence of the rudest sort. In the satisfaction of these few 
 wants he is, according to our modern standards, remarkably inef- 
 ficient. P>om the best natural resources he manages to get a 
 very poor living, depending as he does largely on the spontaneous 
 products of nature. Magic and ritual are very generally relied, 
 upon as aids to wealth production. Primitive man is improvi- 
 dent, for he does not feel keenly the uncertainties of the future, 
 and fails to make provision for them. Hence we find him sub- 
 jected to alternate periods of starvation and plenty. Only a scanty 
 population is possible in this stage, as a tribe must have a large 
 expanse of territory from which to draw its sustenance. The 
 place of abode is easily changed, and warfare with neighboring 
 tribes frequent. Cannibalism is found among many primitive 
 peoples. Private property in land is absent, although the begin- 
 ning of the institution of ownership appears in the recognition of 
 the individual's right to articles of personal use. There is little 
 division of labor. What one man can do, all can do. The soil 
 
 1 Ratzel, History of Mankind, trans, by A. J. Butler, Vol. II, pp. 380-382.
 
 32 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 cultivation by the women and the specialized work of the medi- 
 cine man are exceptions. As each tribe is economically self-suffi- 
 cient, the development of trade is slight. The beginning of 
 slavery may be observed, but this institution plays no impor- 
 tant part in the economy of primitive man, except among the most 
 advanced tribes. 
 
 II. THE PASTORAL STAGE 
 
 In the older accounts of economic evolution, the impression is 
 given that hunting peoples learned to domesticate animals arid 
 then led a pastoral life, later learning to subdue the vegetable 
 kingdom, and then becoming agriculturalists. This view is not 
 accurate. It is possible that the domestication of animals was 
 developed in regions where considerable progress had been made 
 in hoe-culture. As this knowledge spread, certain tribes became 
 and remained pastoral nomads in regions where agriculture was 
 impossible. But whatever the actual steps may have been, the 
 pastoral peoples represent a type of culture that is lower than that 
 of the agricultural stage (as distinguished from hoe-culture), and 
 higher than that of the hunter. Within this stage also are classed 
 together tribes of varying advancement. Illustrations of existing 
 pastoral life are found in the tribes of central Asia, many of the 
 Arabian and African tribes, and the Todas of India. Attempts 
 have been made to trace the pastoral stage in the early history of 
 the Hebrews, Germans, Greeks, and Britons. 
 
 Characteristics of Pastoral Peoples. Some marked features of 
 the first stage are found also among pastoral peoples. A fixed 
 abode is not possible, as food must be found for the herds and flocks. 
 Cities do not develop. Moreover, while the land will now sup- 
 port many more inhabitants per square mile than before, much 
 land is still needed for pasture, and there is frequent collision and 
 warfare between neighboring tribes. It follows also that there is 
 very little private ownership of land among these peoples. Tribes 
 as a whole lay claim to certain districts and try to keep other 
 tribes from pasturing on them. In this stage there are frequently 
 individual accumulations of wealth, consisting mostly of herds or
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 33 
 
 flocks, and thus the contrast between rich and poor makes its ap- 
 pearance. Customary rules regarding the inheritance of wealth 
 are recognized. But this early wealth does not produce com- 
 merce to any considerable extent, simply because there is little 
 division of labor either between localities or within the tribe. 
 
 III. THE AGRICULTURAL STAGE 
 
 In this stage there is an enormous increase in man's power over 
 nature. The production of wealth is increased especially by the 
 use of animal power in cultivating the soil. One result is to in- 
 crease population. Land which under the more primitive meth- 
 ods of production would give a scanty support to a small tribe 
 for a part of the year will now maintain a whole community with 
 a fixed abode. It is necessary for human development that men 
 should live in definite places and have homes and a country. 
 This results in new relations between men, new duties, new arts, 
 and new possibilities. The beginning of the institution of private 
 ownership in land falls within this stage, although it is difficult to 
 trace the actual steps in the process. 
 
 A most important characteristic of this period is slavery. Slav- 
 ery begins long before improved agriculture, but it now attains 
 its full magnitude as an institution. There have been many dis- 
 cussions as to whether slavery is right or wrong. It is both. 
 There is a time in human development when slavery represents a 
 step in human progress. The slavery of the early period we are 
 now considering was inevitable, and is not to be judged by modern 
 standards. We now know that free labor is better than slave 
 labor, especially in the later stages of industrial development; 
 but, inasmuch as primitive man is induced with difficulty to work 
 at all, slave labor is a great improvement on free idleness. 
 
 Commercial intercourse is still comparatively slight in this stage. 
 Fixed residence develops village communities, and these are econom- 
 ically self-sufficient. They produce the things that they consume, 
 and as a rule have not surplus products to dispose of to others. 
 Hence money does not at this time perform important functions 
 in the life of every day. The economic condition of Europe dur- 
 D
 
 34 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ing the middle ages before the growth of cities illustrates the 
 agricultural stage. 
 
 The Manorial Economy in England. England was almost 
 wholly agricultural for three centuries following the Norman Con- 
 quest. In the thirteenth century the population for the most part 
 lived in villages or manors, each controlled by a lord to whom 
 the rest of the inhabitants were bound by customary rules to ren- 
 der certain assistance in the cultivation of the lord's land. The 
 villagers were of various classes, according to the amount of land 
 which they held and according to the services which they were 
 required to perform. The land of each tenant was not a com- 
 pact area, but was composed of strips scattered in the three 
 great fields into which the arable land was divided for purposes 
 of crop rotation. 
 
 Some handicraftsmen were also found upon the estate, but they do not 
 occupy an important place in the economy of the village. For the most part, 
 they were probably slaves or household servants. Slaves in England con- 
 stituted at the time of the Conquest about nine per cent of the population, 
 but "in some of the eastern and midland shires do not appear at all, or fall 
 to a percentage of four or five," while they rise to as much as twenty-four 
 per cent in other parts of the country. "We cannot but explain this by the 
 supposition that in the later stages of the English conquest a greater number 
 of the British cultivators were spared, so that in these districts slaves came to 
 form a considerable part of the rural population. Absolute slavery, how- 
 ever, disappeared in less than a century after the Conquest, and the servi 
 became customary holders of small plots, like the cotters elsewhere, but on 
 more onerous conditions." l 
 
 While these manors were largely self-sufficient in their economic 
 life, there was, to be sure, some trade. England exported raw 
 products to the continent and received back some of the finer 
 forms of manufacture. But the ordinary needs of the very frugal 
 life which the tenants had to live were supplied by products of 
 the village itself. During the centuries following the Norman 
 Conquest important changes took place in the manorial system: 
 (i) a rapid growth in the number of free tenants; (2) the com- 
 mutation of customary services into fixed payments in money or 
 kind; and (3) the appearance of a class of agricultural laborers 
 
 1 See Ashley, English Economic History, Vol. I, pp. 17-18.
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 35 
 
 dependent on the wages which they received. In contrasting the 
 manorial economy with the village of the present day, Professor 
 W. J. Ashley has pointed out the following differences: (i) Now 
 farmers live in separate homesteads among the fields they rent, 
 but then all the cultivators lived side by side in the village street. 
 (2) Now each farmer follows his own judgment as to his agricul- 
 tural operations, but in this early period he took his share in the 
 common method of cultivation, which was regulated by custom 
 enforced by the manor courts. (3) To-day, if the landlord him- 
 self engages in farming, his management is independent of that 
 of his tenants, but under the manorial system he depended almost 
 exclusively upon the labor of his tenants, who contributed plows, 
 oxen, and men. Finally, (4) aside from the great gulf between 
 lord and tenants, there was then no such social separation between 
 the cultivators as there is to-day between large and small farmers. 
 The manorial economy of England was a type, though somewhat 
 more systematically developed, of conditions on the continent of 
 Europe. 
 
 IV. THE HANDICRAFT STAGE 
 
 This stage begins with the development of towns as centers of 
 trade and handicraft in the latter part of the middle ages, and ex- 
 tends to the introduction of power manufacture in the latter part of 
 the eighteenth century. During such a long period many changes 
 took place in the economic life of the people of Europe, but so 
 far as the expansion and satisfaction of wants is concerned, the 
 power over nature, the whole period is in marked contrast with 
 the modern era of machine production. 
 
 Gilds. The growth of trade in the town brought with it the 
 merchant gild, the purpose of which was to regulate the conduct 
 of trade and to keep a monopoly of it for the merchants of the 
 town. Merchant gilds appeared in all the larger towns of Eng- 
 land in the twelfth century. But a new class was developing in 
 the towns, the craftsmen who were engaged in the making of 
 things for sale. As this handicraft grew in importance, the mer- 
 chant gild was superseded by the craft gild, which in England 
 attained its fullest development in the first half of the fourteenth
 
 36 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 century. Each craft had its gild, which specified in detail how 
 the business should be carried on, how many should be admitted 
 to it, and how the trade should be learned. This growth in spe- 
 cialization meant also a growth in trade, but in this early part of 
 the handicraft period, commerce was much restricted as compared 
 with that of the present day. The towns made exchanges mostly 
 with the country surrounding them, there being as yet no national 
 or world market of any importance. Plainly such a general sys- 
 tem of exchange cannot be carried on by barter, and in this period 
 money became increasingly important. 
 
 The agricultural stage had in the greater part of Europe cul- 
 minated in the feudal system. The nobility maintained order 
 and attended to the fighting while the serfs tilled the soil. The 
 manufacturing cities became the rivals of the feudal lords, who 
 felt their power threatened, and hence they bitterly opposed the 
 cities. The cities were free, and the serfs who fled to them were 
 accepted and made freemen. 
 
 The Domestic System. With the beginning of the modern 
 period the town system gave way to a larger economy. The 
 towns lost the control of trade. The gild system was succeeded 
 by the domestic system, which prevailed in England from the 
 middle of the fifteenth to the middle of the eighteenth centuries. 
 As in the gild system, industry was carried on by hand in a small 
 way, but the functions of merchant and workman were now sep- 
 arated. The gild master sold the goods which he produced in his 
 shop directly to the customers who were to use the goods, but 
 under the domestic system the workman came to be less inde- 
 pendent. He received the raw material from a middleman, to 
 whom he also delivered the finished product. Much of this work 
 was done outside of the towns, the artisans thus being enabled to 
 devote part of their time to agriculture. Defoe, in his tour 
 through Great Britain (1724-1726), describes the methods em- 
 ployed as follows : 
 
 The land " was divided into small inclosures from two acres to six or seven 
 each, seldom more ; every three or four pieces of land had an house belonging 
 to them, . . . hardly an house standing out of a speaking distance from 
 another. . . . We could see at every house a tenter, and on almost every
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 37 
 
 tenter a piece of cloth or kersie or shaloon. ... At every considerable 
 house was a manufactury. . . . Every clothier keeps one horse, at least, 
 to carry his manufactures to the market, and every one generally keeps a 
 cow or two or more for his family. By this means the small pieces 
 of inclosed land about each house are occupied, for they scarce sow corn 
 enough to feed their poultry. . . . The houses are full of lusty fellows, some 
 at the dye-vat, some at the looms, others dressing the cloths ; the women or 
 children carding or spinning, being all employed, from the youngest to the 
 oldest." 
 
 The domestic system should be distinguished from the mano- 
 rial economy of the agricultural period, for the production under 
 the domestic system was not for home consumption simply, but 
 for the market. 
 
 Agricultural Changes. During the handicraft period there 
 were also important changes in the agricultural life of England. 
 The most prominent of these is the process of inclosing the com- 
 mon fields for the purpose of pasturage during the Tudor period. 
 Later, the farmers practiced what was known as "convertible hus- 
 bandry"; that is, the pasture was plowed up every few years for 
 raising crops. This, again, has been superseded by the modern 
 system of crop rotation. 
 
 The Mercantile System. The decay of town authority did not 
 imply that industry and commerce were left to the free play of 
 competition. The supervision of the central government took 
 the place of that of the towns. The national system of regula- 
 tion has been called the Mercantile System, which prevailed in 
 England in the sixteenth, seventeenth, and most of the eighteenth 
 centuries. Its essential idea is the guidance of economic affairs 
 in such a way as to increase the commercial and military power 
 of the nation as a whole. The navigation laws which the student 
 has met with in his study of American history were a part of this 
 system. An attempt was made to create a "favorable" balance 
 of trade and to maintain a good supply of the precious 
 metals. Agriculture was fostered with the aim of promoting the 
 growth of population. The mercantile system has often been de- 
 scribed as consisting chiefly of trade restrictions, but it is the con- 
 tention of Professor Schmoller that in its essence the system meant 
 "the replacing of a local and territorial economic policy by that
 
 38 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of the national state." Within the nation it tended to make 
 trade free. 
 
 It was characteristic of the mercantile system, too, to interfere 
 in the conduct of internal trade. Prices, wages, and the rules of 
 apprenticeship were fixed by public authority. The quality of 
 goods was inspected by public officials. Patents of monopoly on 
 the sale of certain commodities, such as gunpowder, matches, and 
 playing cards, were extensively granted by royal authority to fa- 
 vored individuals or companies, ostensibly to foster new industries. 
 
 "At the Council of York, Charles was obliged to declare many of the 
 industrial patents void; but enough remained to call forth an indignant 
 declamation from Sir J. Colepepper in the Long Parliament: 'I have but 
 one Grievance more to offer unto you ; but this one compriseth many ; it 
 is a nest of wasps, or swarm of vermin, which have overcrept the land, 
 I mean the monopoler and polers of the people. These like the frogs of 
 Egypt, have got possession of our dwellings, and we have scarce a room free 
 from them ; they sip in our cup, they dip in our dish, they sit by our fire ; 
 we find them in the dye-vat, wash-bowl, and powdery tub ; they share with 
 the butler in his box, they have marked us and sealed us from head to foot. 
 Mr. Speaker, they will not bate us a pin ; we may not buy our own cloaths 
 without their brokage. These are the leeches that have sucked the com- 
 monwealth so hard that it is almost become hectical. And some of these 
 are ashamed of their right names; they have a vizard to hide the brand 
 made by that good law in the last Parliament of King James; they shelter 
 themselves under the name of a corporation ; they make bye-laws which 
 serve their turns to squeeze us and to fill their purses ; unface these and they 
 will prove as bad curs as any in the pack. These are not petty chapmen, but 
 wholesale men.' " 1 
 
 A full account of this stage in English history would deal with 
 (i) the regulation of labor, including the Statute of Artificers 
 passed in the reign of Elizabeth, which provided that all able- 
 bodied men might be compelled to serve as agricultural laborers, 
 and that all artificers, rural or urban, should undergo an appren- 
 ticeship of at least seven years. In this same reign provision was 
 made for the assessment of wages by the Justices of the Peace. 
 Every year in each locality the justices were to assemble, and, 
 " calling to them such discreet and grave persons ... as they 
 
 1 Cunningham, English Commerce and Industry, Modern Times, Part I pp. 
 307-8.
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 39 
 
 shall think meet, and conferring together respecting the plenty or 
 scarcity of the time," they were to fix the wages for every kind 
 of manual labor, skilled or unskilled, by the year, week, or day, 
 and with or without allowance of food. (2) The stage would deal 
 further with the development of systematic poor relief by civil 
 authority ; (3) the encouragement of shipping and of (4) the im- 
 migration of foreign artisans to introduce new industries; (5) the 
 regulation of the corn trade; (6) the establishing of plantations 
 in the colonies; (7) the regulation of the coinage; (8) the develop- 
 ment of banking, insurance, and foreign commerce, and the decay 
 of the old notions regarding the sinfulness of interest taking. 
 
 V. THE INDUSTRIAL STAGE 
 
 In the latter part of the eighteenth century, the slow-going 
 methods of the handicraft stage were radically changed by the 
 Industrial Revolution. The fundamental feature of this change 
 is the introduction of power manufacture. The industrial revo- 
 lution and the chief features of the Industrial stage will be dis- 
 cussed in the following chapter. 
 
 Before proceeding to the consideration of the last stage, it may 
 be well to notice some of the other views which have been expressed 
 concerning the periods of economic development. The German 
 economist, Hildebrand, has taken as his principle of classification 
 the method of exchanging goods, and from this standpoint he gets 
 the following three stages : (i) barter, (2) money, and (3) credit. 
 All three methods of exchanging, to be sure, are in use at the pres- 
 ent time, but the extensive use of credit is the new and character- 
 istic thing about present-day exchange. It has been objected that 
 the period before the use of money became prominent is charac- 
 terized not so much by the barter of goods as by the fact that 
 exchange itself is unimportant. 
 
 Another writer (Biicher) has divided economic history accord- 
 ing to the length of time which elapses between the production 
 and the consumption of commodities, as follows: 
 
 1. The independent domestic economy. 
 
 2. The town economy. 
 
 3. The national economy.
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 In the first stage the interval between the production and con- 
 sumption is small. Things are produced where they are consumed, 
 as in the village communities of the early middle ages. In the town 
 economy the interval is somewhat greater. The artisans in the 
 town produce for the consumption of other persons, for the most 
 part in the immediate neighborhood, so that the producer meets 
 the consumer without intermediaries. In the third stage, produc- 
 tion is for a national market, so that goods may pass through many 
 hands before reaching the consumer. Possibly, according to this 
 view, a fourth stage might be added, that of a world economy. 
 
 Again, we might pay attention chiefly to the condition of labor. 
 Beginning with a condition where there is no distinct laboring 
 class, we pass through slavery and serfdom to free labor, regu- 
 lated at first by law and custom, and then the free laborer arranges 
 
 THE ECONOMIC STAGES 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 STANDPOINT 
 
 FROM 
 BOCHER'S 
 
 FROM 
 HILDEBRAND'S 
 
 FROM 
 THE LABOR 
 
 ILLUSTRATIONS 
 FROM ENGLISH 
 
 OF PRODUC- 
 
 STANDPOINT 
 
 STANDPOINT 
 
 STANDPOINT 
 
 HISTORY 
 
 TION 
 
 
 
 
 
 I. 
 
 
 
 
 
 Direct Ap- 
 
 
 
 
 Prehistoric 
 
 propriation 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 2. 
 
 Domestic 
 
 Barter 
 
 Laboring 
 
 
 Pastoral 
 
 
 Economy 
 
 class not dif- 
 
 Before Christ 
 
 
 Economy 
 
 
 ferentiated 
 
 
 3- 
 
 
 
 Slavery and 
 
 nth-i4th 
 
 Agricultural 
 
 
 
 Serfdom 
 
 Centuries 
 
 4- 
 Handicraft 
 
 Town 
 Economy 
 
 Money 
 Economy 
 
 Free Labor 
 governed 
 by Custom 
 
 I3th-i8th 
 Centuries 
 
 5- 
 Industrial 
 
 National 
 Economy 
 
 Credit 
 Economy 
 
 Individual 
 Contract 
 Group 
 
 i8th Century 
 to the Pres- 
 ent Time 
 
 
 
 
 Contract 

 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 41 
 
 the conditions of work by individual contract, and finally to an 
 increasing extent by group contract or collective bargaining. 
 
 These various classifications are not contradictory; on the con- 
 trary, they supplement each other. Still other divisions are pos- 
 sible. In the preceding table these various points of view are 
 correlated and applied to the history of England. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Write a description of the economic life of a tribe in one of the first two 
 stages. 
 
 2. What are the theories concerning the origin of cannibalism ? 
 
 3. What is the extent of slavery in Africa at the present time ? 
 
 4. Sketch the development of the woolen industry in England to 1760. 
 
 5. Give an account of the origin of the Bank of England. 
 
 6. Summarize the history of poor relief in England. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ANDREWS, C. M. The Old English Manor. 
 
 ASHLEY, W. J. English Economic History, Vol. I. 
 
 BUCHER, KARL. Industrial Evolution (trans, by S. M. Wickett). 
 
 CHEYNEY, E. P. Industrial and Social History of England, Chaps. I to VII. 
 
 CUNNINGHAM, W. Growth of English Industry and Commerce, Vol. I 
 
 (Middle Ages) and Vol. II (Mercantile System). 
 ELY, R. T. Evolution of Industrial Society, Part I, Chap. III. 
 LUBBOCK, SIR JOHN. Prehistoric Times, Chap. I. 
 MORGAN, L. H. Ancient Society, Chap. I. 
 PRICE, L. L. A Short History of English Commerce and Industry, Chaps. I 
 
 to VIII. 
 
 PRICE, W. H. English Patents of Monopoly. 
 RATZEL, F. History of Mankind (trans, by A. J. Butler), 3 vols. 
 SCHMOLLER, G. The Mercantile System (Economic Classics, edited by W. J. 
 
 Ashley). 
 
 SEEBOHM, F. The English Village Community. 
 STANLEY, H. M. In Darkest Africa, Vol. I, Chap. XXIII. 
 WALLACE, A. R. Russia (edition of 1905), Chap. VIII. 
 WARNER, T. Landmarks in English Industrial History, Chaps. I to XIV.
 
 CHAPTER IV 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY (Continued) 
 
 The Industrial Revolution. The passage from the handicraft 
 to the industrial stage in England is generally known as the In- 
 dustrial Revolution. It has been objected that this term is mis- 
 leading because the introduction of the modern factory system 
 required many years and was but the working out of conditions 
 that had been long maturing. It is true that the growth in the 
 division of labor, the expansion of commerce, and the technical 
 progress of former ages were necessary preliminaries to the in- 
 dustrial revolution, but there is little danger of overemphasizing 
 the importance or the rapidity of the change. The period from 
 1770 to 1840, the span of a single life, is, after all, a short period 
 from the standpoint of the historian. Yet the changes of this 
 period swept away the inefficient methods that had been used for 
 centuries, and caused profound modifications in social structure. 
 To understand the nature of this movement, we must review the 
 condition of things before it began. 
 
 England in 1760. England was at this time largely self-suffic- 
 ing in its economic life, producing for itself its food and other 
 articles of ordinary consumption, although compared with medi- 
 aeval days there had been a marked expansion of international 
 and colonial trade. Woolen goods were the most important ex- 
 port. The imports consisted largely of wines, spirits, rice, sugar, 
 coffee, oil, and furs, and some wool, hemp, silk, and linen yarn. 
 Within the nation, too, there was not such a degree of specializa- 
 tion of industry in particular localities as is found at the present 
 day, although the beginning of such localization had clearly been 
 made in the textile and iron industries. On the whole, however, 
 the commerce between the different sections of the country was 
 
 42
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 43 
 
 slight. The means of transportation were exceedingly poor, not- 
 withstanding the growth of turnpike roads. The roads were de- 
 scribed by a traveler as "most execrably vile." Such was their 
 condition that pack horses were still a common means of getting 
 goods to market. Rivers were important highways, canal build- 
 ing having barely begun. 
 
 The system of hand manufacture was still in general operation. 
 Although the workmen under the domestic system were no longer 
 owners of the material upon which they worked, yet the tools 
 they used were their property. The beginnings of certain fea- 
 tures of the factory system, however, are to be seen long before 
 the use of power machinery, for in some cases workmen were em- 
 ployed in large numbers in buildings owned by the employer, who 
 also furnished the mechanical equipment. But to a large extent 
 manufacturing was combined with agriculture, not only in the 
 textile trades, but in other branches also. "At West Bromwich, a 
 chief center of the metal trade, agriculture was still carried on 
 as a subsidiary pursuit by the metal workers." 
 
 The mediaeval system of common field tillage was extensively 
 used, a large part of the land being still uninclosed. The culti- 
 vation was exceedingly poor, but important experiments tending 
 toward a "new agriculture" were being made in the second quar- 
 ter of the eighteenth century by JethroTull and "Turnip" Town- 
 shend. Of the whole number of farms, approximately one half 
 "were owned and occupied by the various classes of freeholders 
 and copyholders; that is, by land-owning farmers." 
 
 The mediaeval notion of government was still nominally in force. 
 Detailed and special legislation was supposed to be the means of 
 securing a well-ordered trade, as explained in the preceding chap- 
 ter. But a tremendous revolt had begun against this whole sys- 
 tem of government. This revolt had its religious and political as 
 well as its economic aspect. The same year that Thomas Jeffer- 
 son wrote the Declaration of Independence, asserting that all 
 men are by nature equal, Adam Smith published the Wealth 
 of Nations, the most influential book ever written on economics. 
 
 "Every individual," said Smith, "is continually exerting himself to find 
 out the most advantageous employment for whatever capital he can command.
 
 44 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 It is his own advantage, indeed, and not that of the society, which he has in 
 view. But the study of his own advantage, naturally, or rather necessarily, 
 leads him to prefer that employment which is most advantageous to society. 
 . . . What is the species of domestic industry which his capital can employ, 
 and of which the produce is likely to be of the greatest value, every in- 
 dividual, it is evident, can, in his local situation, judge much better than any 
 statesman or lawgiver can for him." l 
 
 The Mechanical Inventions. During the last half of the eight- 
 eenth century the progress of invention was exceptionally rapid. 
 Kay's flying shuttle (1738) had facilitated the weaving process to 
 such an extent that it became difficult to secure enough yarn from 
 the spinners. Hand spinning was improved by Hargreave's 
 "jenny" about 1767; Arkwright, in 1771, made a practical success 
 of roller spinning (a method patented long before), using horse 
 power, and later, water power. Crompton combined these two 
 processes in 1779. After 1785 steam power was applied to cotton 
 spinning, and then it was the weaving process that was felt to be 
 too slow. Cartwright began his experiments in 1784, but the 
 power loom did not come into general use until early in the nine- 
 teenth century. 
 
 The improvement in the steam engine also made possible great 
 advances in the iron industry, of fundamental importance in an 
 age of machinery. The production of English iron was over sev- 
 enty-five times as great in 1840 as it had been in 1740. 
 
 The need for better transportation was met by improved roads, 
 by the building of canals (especially 1790 to 1805), and by the 
 development of steam locomotion. The germ of the modern rail- 
 way is seen in the tramways used in the coal mines. Cast iron 
 rails were used as early as 1738. The first tramway to be used 
 for public purposes was chartered in 1801, the cars to be drawn 
 by horse power. Trevithick made a locomotive in 1803 that was 
 of practical use. In 1814 Stephenson constructed a locomotive 
 that could draw a load of thirty tons at the rate of three miles an 
 hour. The Stockton and Darlington road was opened in 1825 
 with a Stephenson locomotive that made fifteen miles an hour, 
 but two years later the directors of the road considered the advisa- 
 bility of abandoning the use of locomotives. In 1829 the direc- 
 
 >A. Smith, Wealth of Nations, Book IV, Chap. II.
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 
 
 45 
 
 tors of the Liverpool and Manchester Railroad arranged a prize 
 contest to determine the practicability of steam locomotion. The 
 success of Stephenson's "Rocket" in meeting the requirements of 
 the contest demonstrated that the new method of locomotion had 
 come to stay. 
 
 "A general survey of the growth of new industrial methods in the textile 
 and iron industries marks out three periods of abnormal activity in the evolu- 
 tion of modern industry. The first is 1780-1795, when the fruits of early 
 inventions were ripened by the effective application of steam to the machine 
 industries. The second is 1830 to 1845, when industry, reviving after the 
 European strife, utilized more widely the new inventions, and expanded under 
 the stimulus of steam locomotion. The third is 1856-1866 (circa), when the 
 construction of machinery by machinery became the settled rule of industry." * 
 
 It is impossible here to review all the lines of progress in inven- 
 tion and discovery. This progress is not confined to mechanical 
 matters, and taken as a whole, undoubtedly has been much more 
 rapid in the nineteenth than in any preceding century. 
 
 Mr. Alfred Russel Wallace says that " to get any adequate comparison with 
 the nineteenth century we must take, not any preceding century or group of 
 centuries, but rather the whole preceding epoch of human history." A 
 basis for his statement is given by the following comparative lists of great 
 inventions and discoveries. One hesitates to make such a comparison, but 
 it possesses some interest : 
 
 OF THE NINETEENTH CENTURY OF ALL PRECEDING AGES 
 
 1. Railways i. The Mariner's Compass 
 
 2. Steamships 2. The Steam Engine 
 
 3. Electric Telegraphs 3. The Telescope 
 
 4. The Telephone 4. The Barometer and Thermometer 
 
 5. Lucifer Matches 5. Printing 
 
 6. Gas Illumination 6. Arabic Numerals 
 
 7. Electric Lighting 7. Alphabetical Writing 
 
 8. Photography 8. Modern Chemistry Founded 
 
 9. The Phonograph 9. Electric Science Founded 
 
 10. Rontgen Rays 10. Gravitation Established 
 
 11. Spectrum Analysis n. Kepler's Laws 
 
 12. Anaesthetics 12. The Differential Calculus 
 
 13. Antiseptic Surgery 13. The Circulation of the Blood 
 
 14. Conservation of Energy 14. Light proved to have Finite 
 
 Velocity 
 
 1 Hobson, Evolution of Modern Capitalism, new edition of 1907, p. 89.
 
 46 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 OF THE NINETEENTH CENTURY OF ALL PRECEDING AGES 
 
 15. Molecular Theory of Gases 15. The Development of Geometry 
 
 1 6. Velocity of Light directly 
 
 measured, and Earth's Ro- 
 tation experimentally shown 
 
 17. The Uses of Dust 
 
 18. Chemistry, Definite Propor- 
 
 tions 
 
 19. Meteors and the Meteoritic 
 
 Theory 
 
 20. The Glacial Epoch 
 
 21. The Antiquity of Man 
 
 22. Organic Evolution established 
 
 23. Cell Theory and Embryology 
 
 24. Germ Theory of Disease, and 
 
 the Function of the Leuco- 
 cytes. 1 
 
 Agricultural Changes. During the Industrial Revolution there 
 were also important changes in agriculture. Bakewell, in the sec- 
 ond half of the eighteenth century, improved the breeds of sheep 
 and cattle. The inclosing of the common fields proceeded with 
 great rapidity, not, as in the sixteenth century, for the purpose of 
 sheep raising, but to permit of more efficient tillage of the soil. 
 Between 1760 and 1850 over seven million acres were inclosed in 
 England. The small land-owning farmer was crowded out, partly 
 because more investment per acre was needed with the new agri- 
 culture, partly because "gentlemen farmers" (men who had made 
 money in other pursuits and took up agriculture because it was 
 fashionable) bought them out, and because the price of land was 
 greatly increased by the desire of wealthy men to build up family 
 estates. To-day practically all English farmers are tenants. The 
 small farmer, who under the domestic system was also frequently 
 a handicraftsman, was thus crushed between the new agriculture 
 and the new industry. 
 
 "Hitherto the rude implements required for the cultivation of the soil, 
 or the household utensils needed for the comfort of daily life, had been made 
 at home. The farmer, his sons, and his servants in the long winter evenings 
 carved the wooden spoons, the platters, and the beechen bowls, plaited wicker 
 
 1 Wallace, The Wonderful Century, pp. 154-155.
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 47 
 
 baskets, fitted handles to the tools, cut willow teeth for rakes and harrows 
 and hardened them in the fire, fashioned ox yokes and forks, twisted willows 
 into the traces of other harness gear. Traveling" carpenters visited farm- 
 houses at rare intervals to perform those parts of work which needed their 
 professional skill. The women plaited the straw for the neck collars, stitched 
 and stuffed sheepskin bags for the cart saddle, wove the straw and hempen 
 stirrups and halters, peeled the rushes for and made the candles. The 
 spinning wheel, the distaff, and the needle were never idle; coarse hand-made 
 cloth and linen supplied all wants; every farmhouse had its brass brewery 
 kettle. . . . All the domestic industries by which cultivators of the soil 
 increased their incomes, or escaped the necessity of .selling their produce, 
 were now supplanted by manufactures." * 
 
 Effects of the Industrial Revolution. As has already been indi- 
 cated, the Industrial Revolution introduces one of the great stages 
 in the development of man's power over nature. But along with 
 the new opportunities came also new dangers and perplexing 
 problems. 
 
 (i) The Factory System. The use of expensive machinery 
 and steam power made it impossible for men to carry on their 
 work in their own homes. The factory supplants the home as 
 the typical unit of production. Instead of working by themselves 
 or with a few assistants, men now to a much greater extent than 
 before must congregate in cities, and submit to a new discipline in 
 large groups organized for purposes of production. This brought 
 with it a new division of society into classes. The machine and 
 the workshop, as well as the raw material and the product, are at 
 no stage in the productive process owned by the men who do the 
 manual work. The masses become wage earners. Now, in some 
 industries not one in a hundred can by exceptional ability become 
 an independent employer, and the workman knows that he is a 
 workman for life. So we have now two industrial classes, laborers 
 and capitalists, with a great gulf between them which compara- 
 tively few men can cross, and with interests which often seem 
 irreconcilable. What the ultimate effects of the new system of 
 production will be cannot be stated, but it has been suggested 
 that these changes in external relations are affecting also men's 
 
 1 Prothero, quoted by Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Com- 
 merce, Modern Times, Part II, p. 722.
 
 48 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 habits of thought. Can we expect the institution of private prop- 
 erty to seem as natural and sacred to those who have nothing to 
 do with the buying and selling of products as to those who engage 
 much in pecuniary transactions? It has been suggested that the 
 feeling that we have a right to the product of our own labor is 
 merely a survival of the era of small-scale hand manufacture. 
 
 (2) The Expansion of Markets and Industrial Specialization. 
 Along with the new methods of production there has been a change 
 from restricted local markets to national and even world markets. 
 Improved methods of transportation make it possible for different 
 branches of production to be localized in regions where there are 
 special facilities for raw material or power. This implies greater 
 economic interdependence and greater liability to trade fluctua- 
 tions and disturbances. One great advantage of the old slow- 
 going system of manufacture and trade was its regularity. As the 
 area of the market increases, manufacturers find it more difficult 
 to decide what and how much to produce. Trade fluctuations 
 have increased in severity with the growth of large-scale produc- 
 tion. This is due not merely to the changing and enlarging de- 
 mand which cannot be calculated, but also to the fact that manu- 
 facture itself is constantly being disturbed by improvements which 
 cannot be foreseen. It is possible that a still larger scale of manu- 
 facture hereafter will bring steadiness in industry, but whatever 
 the cause of these fluctuations, the effect upon the wage earner is 
 demoralizing. If he were wise enough to save his earnings dur- 
 ing good times, and so have something for hard times, he would 
 not suffer so much. But very few people who live in abundance 
 can do this; how much less those whose condition even in good 
 times is one of meager comfort ! 
 
 Evils of the Transitional Period. The condition of the English 
 working classes in the latter part of the eighteenth and early nine- 
 teenth centuries was undoubtedly worse than in any other period 
 in the history of the country. It is difficult to say to what extent 
 this was due to the introduction of the factory system. In addi- 
 tion to the new methods of manufacture there were wars, peculiar 
 facts about land ownership, duties, and taxes. There is some 
 evidence that the condition of child workers under the domestic
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 49 
 
 system was often worse than in the factories, their parents prov- 
 ing the hardest taskmasters. 
 
 "The evils and horrors of the industrial revolution are often vaguely 
 ascribed to the ' transition stage ' brought about by the development of ma- 
 chinery and the consequent ' upheaval.' But the more we look into the matter, 
 the more convinced we become that the factory system and machinery merely 
 took what they found, and that the lines on which the industrial revolution 
 actually worked itself out cannot be explained by the progress of material 
 civilization alone ; rather, the disregard of child-life, the greed of child-labour, 
 and the maladministration of the poor law had, during the eighteenth century, 
 and probably much farther back still, been preparing the human material 
 that was to be so mercilessly exploited." * 
 
 But whatever the causes, the facts that have been revealed re- 
 garding the conditions in English mines and factories of this period 
 are amazing. The picture includes cruelty to apprenticed chil- 
 dren, excessive hours, and unhealthful conditions of work. The 
 evils were worst in the smaller factories, the owners of which were 
 hard pressed by relentless competition. Outside of the factories, 
 also, those who attempted to continue to work in their homes in 
 the old way suffered from irregular employment and low earn- 
 ings. The distress of the hand-loom weavers affords an illustra- 
 tion. 
 
 Competition and Laissez-faire. We have seen that Adam 
 Smith advocated liberty. He asserted that every man, if allowed 
 to do as he pleased, would sooner or later do that for which he 
 /as best fitted, and would consequently work where he could get 
 the most wages. Every man would buy what suited him best, 
 and, after some experiment, manufacturers would make what was 
 called for. If one line of work was more profitable than another, 
 more men would go into it and by their competition would bring 
 prices down. If men cheated their customers, the men would go 
 somewhere else, and cheating would not pay. Everywhere men 
 would look out for their own interests and would make the bar- 
 gain that was most advantageous to themselves. This system of 
 balanced self-interests resulting from competition was the best 
 regulator possible, infinitely better, he claimed, than the old-time 
 laws, which only incumbered the development of industry. If 
 
 1 Hutchins and Harrison, A History of Factory Legislation, p. 13. 
 E
 
 50 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the policy of industrial freedom were adopted, he prophesied a 
 great increase in the national production of wealth. 
 
 This view gained in favor during the Industrial Revolution. Not 
 that a wholesale repeal of the old laws occurred, such things 
 never happen in England, and are difficult anywhere, but there 
 is a quiet and effective way of changing laws by changing men's 
 ideas regarding them and leaving them unenforced. A law that 
 has been long observed has often to be long dead before people 
 gain the courage to repeal it. So the law requiring seven years' 
 apprenticeship before one could enter certain trades quietly died 
 during the eighteenth century, and when, finally, in the labor 
 troubles early in the nineteenth century, some workmen in desper- 
 ation discovered the old law and prosecuted employers for violat- 
 ing it, the law was first suspended and then repealed, as being 
 plainly ill adapted to the new condition of industry. So, little by 
 little, the old laws were repealed or forgotten, and men were left 
 free to bargain and manufacture as they pleased. 
 
 This policy of laissez-faire, or letting things drift, was very gen- 
 erally accepted by the economic writers who followed Adam Smith, 
 and was clearly reflected in the parliamentary debates. The uni- 
 versal free play of competition came to be the prevailing ideal in 
 this first phase of the industrial stage. It was in keeping with 
 this spirit that England became a free-trade nation in this period, 
 the last step being taken when the "corn laws" were repealed in 
 1846, the act going into effect in 1849. 
 
 The Reaction against the Passive Policy. It may be said that 
 by 1850 the abandonment of mercantilistic ideas was complete in 
 England, but long before this date a new system of legislation was 
 enacted for the purpose of controlling industry. The government 
 could not ignore the actual condition that resulted from competi- 
 tion and the introduction of machinery. We have now to con- 
 sider some of the main lines of development of industrial regula- 
 tion. 
 
 (i) The Quality of Goods. In repealing the laws for the in- 
 spection of wares it was urged that cheating would not pay and 
 would cure itself. Indeed, it was said that the very inspection of 
 wares by the government was the cause of fraud; for, the govern-
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 51 
 
 ment brand being often put on carelessly, men bought poor goods, 
 because of the brand, which they would have rejected if they had 
 examined them. The abolition of the laws would result in each ex- 
 amining goods for himself, it was asserted. It is hardly necessary 
 to say that these hopes were not realized. Men might be trusted 
 to attend their own interests if they knew enough to do so, but 
 they do not. Who can tell the quality of baking powder, or ground 
 spices, or patent medicines, or many other things that are misrep- 
 resented when offered for sale? For these the ordinary buyer's 
 knowledge is worthless; an expert must be employed. Such has 
 been the experience of the English people and also, more recently, 
 of the people of the United States, and the law now provides for 
 the inspection by government experts of many articles of food. 
 The theory that men will ruin their business prospects if they cheat, 
 and so will be deterred from cheating, has been utterly exploded 
 by this great English experiment. The reputation for honesty is 
 undoubtedly a source of strength to many business houses; but 
 many a man has perpetrated an audacious fraud upon a country 
 for a few years and retired with a fortune when his cheating began 
 to be known. The inspection of goods by the State is a principle 
 now fully recognized, the only question being how far it should 
 be applied. 
 
 (2) The Protection of Labor. As a result of a series of epi- 
 demics of infectious fevers, public attention was called to the con- 
 dition of the apprenticed children in cotton factories. In 1 796 the 
 Manchester Board of Health reported upon the unhealthful con- 
 ditions under which the children worked, pointing out that "the 
 untimely labour of the night, and the protracted labour of the 
 day, with respect to children, not only tends to diminish future 
 expectations as to the general sum of life and industry, by impair- 
 ing the strength and destroying the vital stamina of the rising gen- 
 eration, but it too often gives encouragement to idleness, extrava- 
 gance and profligacy in the parents, who, contrary to the order 
 of nature, subsist by the oppression of their offspring." In 1802 
 the first factory act was passed to protect the health and morals of 
 pauper children in cotton factories. The apprentices were not to 
 vrork more than twelve hours by day, and after 1804 not at all by
 
 52 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 night, but the law was not effectively administered. After much 
 agitation, in which Robert Owen took a prominent part, a second 
 step was taken in 1819. The act prohibited children under nine 
 years from working in cotton mills, and no person under sixteen 
 was to be employed more than twelve hours per day. As with the 
 act of 1802, the enforcement of the law was left to the justices of 
 the peace. In 1833 regulations as to conditions of work for chil- 
 dren and young persons were made for all textile factories, and 
 special inspectors were provided to enforce the law. In the fol- 
 lowing years the controversy concerning labor legislation was vio- 
 lent and bitter. After a report by a committee revealing shameful 
 conditions in the mines, an act was passed in 1842 prohibiting the 
 employment of women and children underground. In 1844 wo- 
 men were included in the protective factory legislation and the 
 half-time system for children was enacted. The Ten Hours' Act 
 of 1847 limited the working day to ten hours. Subsequently, pro- 
 tective legislation was made to cover industrial establishments gen- 
 erally. These various laws were consolidated in 1878, and again 
 in 1901. Laws now in force provide for (i) the fencing in of 
 dangerous machinery; (2) sanitation in factories; (3) a minimum 
 age and schooling for children at work; (4) limitation of the hours 
 of work for women and children. There is no direct regulation 
 of the hours of adult male workers, nor of the wages of any 
 class of workers. 
 
 Another important line of legislation that has been made neces- 
 sary by the extensive use of machinery deals with the liability of 
 employers in cases of accidents to their workmen. Under the 
 common law a workman was entitled to receive damages when 
 injured as a result of the negligence of his employers, but he was 
 supposed to assume the ordinary risks of the business. When 
 the injury was caused by the workman's own negligence or by 
 the negligence of a fellow- workman, the employer was not respon- 
 sible. The Employers' Liability Act of 1880 gave the workman a 
 right to compensation also in certain cases where the injury was 
 caused by the negligence of other employees, but in 1897, by the 
 Workmen's Compensation Act, a radical departure was made from 
 previous legislation. The employer is now liable to pay damages
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 53 
 
 even when there has been no negligence on his own part, and even 
 when the accident has been due to the neglect of the injured work- 
 man himself, except only in cases of "serious and willful miscon- 
 duct." This principle now applies also to agriculture, shipping, 
 and mercantile and domestic employments, and certain trade dis- 
 eases have been made to count as accidents. 
 
 (3) Labor Organizations. Modifications in the working of 
 free competition have also been effected by the voluntary organi- 
 zation of the worker, not only by their influence upon legislation, 
 but also by direct dealings with employers. We have noticed the 
 gilds, which played a large part in the history of the middle ages. 
 These, however, were not like modern trades unions. They were 
 unions of men who worked, but not exclusively of wage earners, 
 nor in the interests of wage earners even chiefly. They were 
 formed of masters. But combinations of the wage-earning classes 
 are found long before the Industrial Revolution. They do not 
 become prominent, however, until the nineteenth century. Laws 
 prohibiting the combination of laborers had been passed at inter- 
 vals since the middle ages, and in 1800 Parliament, finding that 
 unions were increasing, passed a most comprehensive law to sup- 
 press them, declaring illegal "all agreements between journeymen 
 and workmen for obtaining advances of wages, reductions of hours 
 of labor, or any other changes in the conditions of work." Under 
 this law many workmen were prosecuted and severely punished, 
 but in vain. In 1824 Parliament confessed the law a mistake, 
 and repealed it along with previous laws relating to combinations 
 of workmen. Trades unions thus tolerated grew at an astonish- 
 ing rate, but they were still subject to legal persecution. Judicial 
 decisions, especially, were adverse to them, as the courts regarded 
 them as agreements in restraint of trade. But in 1871 a law was 
 passed which declared that the purposes and actions of trades 
 unions were not to be deemed unlawful as being in the restraint 
 of trade, and in 1875 the legality of trades unions was still further 
 recognized by the provision that acts which were not punishable 
 as crimes when done by one person should not be indictable as 
 conspiracy when done by two or more in furtherance of trade dis- 
 pute, and finally, in 1906, the courts were forbidden to entertain
 
 54 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 actions for damages against trades unions. In this same year 
 peaceful picketing was legalized. 
 
 (4) The Extension of Government Enterprise. The reaction 
 against a laissez-faire policy is further shown by a growth in the 
 sphere of industry directly managed by the government. We find 
 municipalities operating street railways and furnishing water, gas, 
 and electric light. Municipal enterprise includes also in various 
 places markets, docks, dwellings, baths, race courses, oyster fish- 
 eries, slaughterhouses, milk depots, employment bureaus, sewage 
 farms, theaters, and many other lines of activity. Again, the na- 
 tional government conducts the postal savings banks, the parcels 
 post, and the telegraph and telephone systems. 
 
 Summary. In this chapter a brief- sketch has been given of 
 England's attempt to deal with a new set of forces. An immense 
 increase in production has taken place, due in part to competition, 
 more to machinery. But the distribution of this wealth, growing 
 directly out of the principles of competition so long as they were 
 unrestrictedly applied, was such that poverty grew rapidly, and 
 some said even faster than wealth, and the laboring population 
 of the realm sank into deeper distress and degradation. The par- 
 tial benevolence of employers, which would fain have mitigated 
 this disaster, was, as a rule, neither welcomed nor tolerated by the 
 competition which had made itself law. Not until this benevo- 
 lence was formulated, generalized, and enforced by disinterested 
 legislation was the horror of the situation diminished. When we 
 hear the principle of "a fair field and no favor" and "no State 
 intervention" advocated by a man strong in the consciousness of 
 personal advantages, we must remember that he is a century be- 
 hind his time, and that he has not read or has not profited by one of 
 the most dolorous chapters in human history. The English nation, 
 after a trial of free competition and no interference, as thorough 
 as could well be made, has undeniably returned to the principle 
 of governmental activity which she had abandoned, a principle 
 which recognizes as the function of the State the protection 
 of the citizens, and the furtherance of their material and social 
 well-being, by every law and every activity which offers a reasona- 
 ble guarantee of contributing to that end. It is to be noticed fur-
 
 THE EVOLUTION OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY 55 
 
 thermore that, as a matter of fact, all this activity of the State con- 
 tributing to material and social well-being has also increased free- 
 dom as a positive, constructive force. It has promoted the growth 
 of individual powers and enlarged the scope of activity of the 
 average citizen. It has not tended to slavery, as Herbert Spencer 
 long ago maintained, but its tendency has been in the direction of 
 the sort of liberty that is really worth while ; namely, liberty as a 
 power of development and of contributing (in the words of the 
 philosopher T. H. Green) to the "common good." 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. What is the origin of the terra " laissez-faire " ? 
 
 2. What laws are in force in your state regarding the inspection of food and 
 other articles offered for sale? 
 
 3. Give a detailed account of the development of one of the great inven- 
 tions. 
 
 4. Give a sketch of the enactment and repeal of the "corn laws." 
 
 5. Give an account of the development of monopolies and trusts in Eng- 
 land. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BEARD, C. The Industrial Revolution. 
 
 CHEYNEY, E. P. Industrial and Social History of England, Chaps. VIII 
 
 and IX. 
 CUNNINGHAM, W. Growth of English Industry and Commerce, Modern 
 
 Times, Part II. Laissez-Faire. 
 
 HOBSON, J. A. Evolution of Modern Capitalism, Chaps. Ill and IV. 
 HOWE, F. C. " Municipal Ownership in Great Britain," Bulletin of the 
 
 United States Bureau of Labor, January, 1906. 
 
 HUTCHINS and HARRISON, A. A History of Factory Legislation, Chap. II. 
 PRICE, L. L. Short History of English Commerce and Industry, Chaps. IX 
 
 andX. 
 TAYLOR, H. C. " The Decline of Land-owning Farmers in England," Bulletin 
 
 of the University of Wisconsin, Economics and Political Science Series, 
 
 No. 142. 
 
 TOYNBEE, A. The Industrial Revolution. 
 VEBLEN, T. B. The Theory of Business Enterprise, Chap. IV.
 
 CHAPTER V 
 THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
 
 THE economic development of the United States has in some 
 respects been very unlike the economic development of England, 
 and yet very like it in other respects. Let us note in the first place 
 the points of difference, the factors and characteristics of our eco- 
 nomic history which are peculiarly American. 
 
 Economic Stages in American Industrial History. The transit 
 of civilization from Europe to America, as an American historian 1 
 has finely phrased it, thrust the European laws, customs, and in- 
 dustrial technique of the seventeenth century into the primitive 
 environment of a wilderness, and for the moment the wilderness 
 dominated. Industry was forced to begin at the beginning and 
 retrace as the child is said to retrace the mental development 
 of mankind the industrial evolution of the race. 
 
 The American people have thus, during the comparatively brief 
 historical period which has elapsed since the settlement of this 
 country, run the whole gamut of industrial evolution, passing 
 through with striking rapidity all the stages differentiated in the 
 preceding chapters. There was slaughter of captives in the In- 
 dian wars, enslavement of Indians, particularly but not only 
 in the Spanish colonies, later the introduction of negro slavery 
 and modified serfdom in the bond or indented servants, then 
 the individual wage contract, still supreme among agricultural 
 laborers, and finally, collective bargaining through the great 
 trades unions of the present generations. In a similar way, 
 practically all the stages differentiated in the table given on page 
 40 may be traced in the industrial evolution of the United 
 States. 
 
 1 Edward Eggleston, Transit of Civilization, New York, 1900. 
 56
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 57 
 
 Naturally it is not to be supposed that American industrial so- 
 ciety worked its own way unaided through all those economic 
 stages which the race, with "painful steps and slow," has labori- 
 ously traversed in its upward march. Stimulated by European 
 culture, we hurried through the earlier stages, for the most part, 
 retracing them merely as an incident of frontier conditions, and 
 skipping some such as the pastoral stage in many sections 
 of the country. On the other hand, it must not be inferred that 
 we have everywhere passed beyond the so-called primitive 
 stages. Barter is still the commonest mode of exchange in some 
 parts of the country, and there are comparatively few rural dis- 
 tricts in which credit transactions have in the main taken the 
 place of money transactions. It is interesting to observe that, 
 owing to the progressive Western movement of the population of 
 the country, the stages in the history of man's productive efforts 
 appeared in regular order from West to East. Thus, a few years 
 ago, the country of the frontier was occupied by hunters and 
 trappers; next were great stretches of country almost entirely de- 
 voted to grazing; farther east, agriculture predominated; trade 
 and commerce were active, especially in the country east of the 
 Mississippi; manufacture on a large scale was prominent in the 
 North Atlantic and North Central groups of states; while finally 
 the large industrial combinations which mark the latest step in 
 development were confined (with respect to legal residence at 
 least) to the Atlantic seaboard. 
 
 Sectionalism. This phenomenon of the contemporaneous ex- 
 istence of several industrial stages, side by side, under the same gov- 
 ernment, has laid upon this country some of the hardest problems 
 which it has had to solve. The ever present but ever reced- 
 ing frontier has continually created a set of interests antagonis- 
 tic to those of the settled industrial and commercial communities. 
 Shays's Rebellion in 1786 was in part a protest of the more 
 thinly settled debtor communities against the determination of 
 the commercial centers to introduce the sound currency which a 
 developed commerce requires. The federal Constitution was 
 adopted and the present government created in order, largely, 
 to strengthen national credit, insure taxation, remove trade
 
 58 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 barriers, and provide a sound currency; and the opposition to the 
 ratification of the Constitution came largely from those agricul- 
 tural and thinly settled communities that wanted to keep paper 
 money, evade debt payment, and resist the collection of taxes. 
 During the earlier history of the country wildcat banking and in- 
 flated currency regularly followed in the wake of the frontier. 
 
 Tariff legislation, with its different appeal to the agricultural 
 and industrial sections of the country, has been another prolific 
 source of territorial conflict. After the War of 1812, the manu- 
 facturing centers of the North redoubled their efforts for protec- 
 tion. This was strenuously resisted by the South, where manu- 
 factures had practically gained no hold, and the struggle of the 
 sections over the tariff led to Nullification in South Carolina and 
 the acceptance by the South of the doctrine of secession. The 
 Civil War itself was largely a sectional quarrel growing out of 
 ceaseless friction between a section which had reached the indus- 
 trial stage and a condition of free-wage contract with a section 
 which had been held in the agricultural stage by the retention of 
 slavery. As a late illustration of sectional conflict arising from 
 the natural clash of districts in different stages of economic devel- 
 opment, we have the free-silver campaign of 1896, when the min- 
 ing, agricultural, and debtor communities of the West and South 
 arrayed themselves against the industrial and creditor communi- 
 ties of the East and North. The typical political struggles of the 
 past have been territorial and sectional; now that the frontier 
 has disappeared, the typical political struggles of the future will 
 take the form, possibly, of class against class. 
 
 Characteristics of the American People. Although the frontier 
 has disappeared, the pioneer work of "winning a continent from 
 nature and subduing it to the uses of man" has left an indelible 
 impress upon the American character. In the beginning the dan- 
 gers and hardships of the frontier acted as a powerful selective 
 force in determining the character of our earlier immigrants, giv- 
 ing us an unusually restless, mobile, and enterprising people. The 
 process of settlement which followed merely emphasized these 
 qualities and added others of a kindred nature. The primitive 
 settler, following the trapper and the trader into the wilderness,
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 59 
 
 was forced to depend upon himself for protection and subsistence; 
 he expected little aid from the government, was unused to the 
 restraints of law, and a little contemptuous of its possibilities, either 
 for good or for evil. The process of settlement, then, merely con- 
 firmed the American in that excessive individualism which has 
 made him independent and resourceful, to be sure, but partial to 
 the spoils system, tolerant of lynch law and labor violence, indif- 
 ferent to waste and weakness in the administration of his govern- 
 ment. 
 
 At the same time the great natural wealth of our land and the 
 ease with which it could be secured from the government have 
 taught our people, particularly in the West, to regard nature rather 
 than thrift as the source of wealth, to exploit rather than create, 
 to work and study as we farm extensively. As a people, we are 
 optimistic but careless, generous but wasteful, buoyant but boast- 
 ful. Industrially, we have risen to our exceptional opportunities 
 with spirit, playing the commercial game at times with excessive 
 energy and devotion; but we have come to emphasize quantity 
 rather than quality, product rather than finish. We "lead the 
 world" in the use of labor-saving machinery, but depend largely 
 upon Europe for our skilled artisans. 
 
 Growth of Population. The mere growth of the American peo- 
 ple has been as striking as it is familiar. In 1640 there were about 
 25,000 persons, excluding Indians, in British North America; 
 about 260,000 at the end of the seventeenth century according to 
 Bancroft; according to the same authority the million mark was 
 reached in 1743; and in 1790 the first federal census showed a 
 population of 3,929,214 in the United States alone. In the next 
 hundred years the population doubled every twenty-five years on 
 an average, and although the rate of increase has fallen off some- 
 what since the Civil War, we are still growing at a marvelous pace, 
 the population of continental United States being estimated at 
 
 82,574,195 in ^QS- 
 
 Despite this enormous increase, there has been at no time any 
 evidence that the population of this country was multiplying more 
 rapidly than the means of subsistence. Wages and incomes in 
 general have risen, not without interruption, but with compara-
 
 60 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tive steadiness, over long periods; and the dismal predictions of 
 overpopulation which were so common in the first half of the nine- 
 teenth century have been signally discredited as practical propo- 
 sitions applicable to the American people of this epoch. The 
 exploitation of national wealth, the perfection of business organi- 
 zation, and the invention of labor-saving machinery have more 
 than kept pace with the population; and it has been discovered 
 that over long periods prosperity and high wages tend to depress 
 rather than to raise the birth rate, even of the wage-earning popu- 
 lation. We are in no danger of a " devastating torrent of chil- 
 dren." 
 
 On the contrary, the real problem of the twentieth century, or 
 at least the problem that has evoked the greatest discussion, is 
 found in the steady decline of the birth rate. According to some 
 of the most eminent authorities, the race is dying at the top, the 
 ablest and most successful people have the smallest families; and 
 this constant sterilization of the ablest stock of the race is, in the 
 opinion of such authorities, second in importance to no problem 
 which Western civilization is called upon to solve. It is not that 
 we want more people. Population is still increasing with suffi- 
 cient rapidity. The problem lies in the apparent failure of the 
 most efficient individuals to multiply as rapidly as certain classes 
 of the less efficient. Other authorities, it should be added, main- 
 tain that this "race suicide" has been going on for centuries, that 
 it has not in the past, and will not in the future, lower the vitality 
 or general efficiency of the race. Such writers view with compla- 
 cency the ceaseless sterilization of the upper classes, maintaining 
 that the process stimulates the ambition of the abler members of 
 the lower classes by creating room at the top, and that so long as 
 the habits and ideals of the upper classes remain wholesome, there 
 is no cause for regret that the individuals who compose these 
 classes are not self-perpetuating. Social heredity, not personal 
 heredity, the preservation of sound morals, wholesome customs, 
 and habits of social helpfulness, together with the opening up of 
 new opportunities, are the important factors. 
 
 Second only in importance to "race suicide," and intimately 
 connected with it, is the problem created by the rush to the city.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 6l 
 
 In 1790 about 33 Americans in every thousand lived in a city of 
 8000 inhabitants or more, in 1900 more than 33 in every hundred 
 lived in a city of this size. The mere facts in this connection are 
 familiar to every one and need no elaboration. Their importance 
 lies in the fact that the rush to the city is apparently universal, 
 that it has been going on for centuries, and that it indefinitely com- 
 plicates and aggravates the social, industrial, and political prob- 
 lems of our time. "Race suicide," for example, is more attribu- 
 table to social conditions created by city life than to any physical 
 incapacity of the women of this generation to bear children; the 
 evils commonly charged to the factory system are due as much 
 to city crowding as to the factory system itself; and, speaking gen- 
 erally, whatever plan of reform for existing evils we devise or 
 champion, we must reckon with this deep-rooted and persistent 
 force which draws to the city so much of the best talent and abil- 
 ity which the rural districts produce. 
 
 Slavery and the Negro Problem. From the earliest period of 
 settlement, one of our fundamental industrial problems has been 
 to get enough labor to exploit the great national wealth of the 
 country. The first solution attempted was by importing bonds- 
 men or indentured servants. "Nearly all the immigrants that 
 came (to Virginia) between 1620 and 1650 were bondsmen," and 
 in 1680 an English official estimated that about 10,000 persons 
 were kidnaped or "spirited away" to America every year. This 
 class of indentured servants consisted of runaway apprentices, 
 penniless debtors, kidnaped children, honest laborers, vagrants, 
 and criminals of all kinds. They were sometimes subject to the 
 most inhuman treatment, but, because they had white skins, soon 
 melted into the free population and never created a race problem. 
 
 The first negro slave landed in Virginia in 1619. For about 
 thirty years they did not increase very rapidly, but after that, and 
 until the close of the eighteenth century, they multiplied with 
 greater rapidity than the white population. In 1790 there were 
 750,208 negroes or persons of negro descent in this country, con- 
 stituting 19.3 percent of the population. Since 1790 the negro 
 population has steadily declined in relative importance, and in 
 1900, numbering 8,840,789 in all, it constituted only n.6 percent
 
 62 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of the general population. The relative decline of the negro popu- 
 lation is probably not due to white immigration, since the natural 
 growth of the white population is markedly greater than that of 
 the negroes in the South, where white immigration has been un- 
 important. 
 
 The negro problem to-day, in so far as it is an economic as dis- 
 tinguished from a political or social problem, arises from the tend- 
 ency of the negroes to concentrate in the cities and in a narrow 
 district of the cotton-growing states known as the black belt; 
 from their shiftlessness, their ignorance, their dependence upon 
 credit advances in the farming districts, and their alarming con- 
 centration in a few occupations, some of which particularly as 
 they practice them are neither educational, uplifting, nor devel- 
 opmental. In 1900, for instance, 63 per cent of the male and 90 
 per cent of the female negro breadwinners were employed in un- 
 skilled trades, and the proportion confined to the unskilled 
 trades shows no signs of diminishing. This condition of affairs is 
 due in some degree to the economic inertia and shiftlessness of 
 the negroes themselves, but it is also due in part to the race preju- 
 dice of their white brethren, which, unfortunately, shows no abate- 
 ment with the passage of time. The trades unions, for instance, 
 evince a growing disinclination to receive negroes as members on 
 the same status as white workingmen. Vigorous efforts are now 
 being made in the South to provide industrial training of a sys- 
 tematic kind for the negroes, and in the future the rather men- 
 acing movement of the present day may be checked or wholly 
 reversed. 
 
 Immigration. Next in importance to the negro question is 
 the problem of immigration. We have always had an immigra- 
 tion problem. "Governor Thomas Dongan, in 1685, made a re- 
 port to the King of England full of dreadful forebodings as to the 
 future of the 'Royal Province' of New England unless the tend- 
 ency to overcrowding were promptly checked. . . . George Wash- 
 ington and Thomas Jefferson are both recorded as opponents of 
 an unrestricted policy of immigration, and it may be safely asserted 
 that no considerable period has elapsed since their day without 
 producing eloquent and forceful advocates of a rigid restrictive
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 63 
 
 immigration policy." 1 Owing, however, to the extraordinary in- 
 crease of immigrants in recent years the number rose from 
 223,299 in 1898 to 1,285,349 in 1907 unusual interest in the 
 subject has been aroused, the restrictive features of our law have 
 been repeatedly strengthened, and a commission has been ap- 
 pointed by Congress to investigate the subject. 
 
 Most of the alarm which has recently been expressed, however, 
 is due to the change in character, rather than the increase in vol- 
 ume, of our immigration. Instructive statistics bearing upon this 
 point are given in Table I on the following page. From this 
 table it appears that until nearly the last decade of the nineteenth 
 century, most of the immigrants came from the United Kingdom, 
 Germany, and northwestern Europe, while since that time the 
 arrivals have been largely from southern Europe; and it is charged 
 that the new immigrants are more illiterate, more given to crime, 
 of poorer physique, and possessed of less property than the earlier 
 immigrants. "These people," it has been said, "have no history 
 behind them which is of a nature to give encouragement. They 
 have none of the inherited instincts and tendencies which made 
 it comparatively easy to deal with the immigration of the earlier 
 time. They are beaten men from beaten races, representing the 
 worst failures in the struggle for existence. Centuries are against 
 them, as centuries were on the side of those who formerly came 
 to us." 2 
 
 There can be no doubt about the real gravity of the problem. 
 In times past charitable associations, and even certain foreign gov- 
 ernments, "assisted" the poorest and neediest of their citizens to 
 migrate to this country; famine and revolution in Europe spurred 
 the impecunious and the radical to take refuge among us; regu- 
 larly, also, the tide of immigration has ebbed and risen in close 
 correspondence with the business prosperity of this country, arti- 
 ficially swelling our laboring population in times of industrial ac- 
 tivity, encouraging our industrial managers in their spasmodic, 
 jerky methods of production, and thus augmenting the severity of 
 
 1 Commissioner of Immigration, Robert Watchorn, in The Outlook, Vol. 87, 
 p. 900. 
 
 * Walker, Discussions in Economics and Statistics, " Restriction of Immigra- 
 tion," p. 447.
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 our alternating periods of industrial depression. Moreover, in 
 certain industries the immigrant with his relatively low standard of 
 living has driven out the native workman; and most of the immi- 
 grants have shown an unfortunate tendency to linger in the cities 
 of the eastern seaboard, swarming in the slums and intensifying 
 all those social evils which have their origin in urban congestion. 
 In the light of history, on the other hand, the immigration prob- 
 lem is far less alarming than it is in the dry light of recent statistics. 
 In the first place, the statistics themselves, as ordinarily published, 
 
 TABLE I 
 
 TOTAL NUMBER OF IMMIGRANTS (IN THOUSANDS) AND PROPORTION COMING 
 FROM DESIGNATED COUNTRIES BY SPECIFIED PERIODS : 1821-1906.' 
 
 
 1821 
 
 1851 
 
 1861 
 
 1871 
 
 1881 
 
 1891 
 
 1901 
 
 
 1850 
 
 1860 
 
 1870 
 
 1880 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 1906 
 
 Total Number, ooo 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 omitted 
 
 241:6 
 
 2?o8 
 
 2TIC. 
 
 2812 
 
 C247 
 
 3844 
 
 4074 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Per cent 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Germany 
 
 24. 2 
 
 36.6 
 
 34.0 
 
 2?. 6 
 
 27.7 
 
 14.1 
 
 4.7 
 
 Great Britain 
 
 I .O 
 
 16.1 
 
 26.2 
 
 IQ. <; 
 
 115.4 
 
 8.0 
 
 e.4 
 
 Ireland 
 
 42.3 
 
 1C. 2 
 
 18.8 
 
 ic.e 
 
 12.1; 
 
 IO.S 
 
 4.4 
 
 Norway, Sweden, and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Denmark 
 
 0.7 
 
 0.9 
 
 5-4 
 
 8.6 
 
 12-5 
 
 9-9 
 
 7.0 
 
 Total 
 
 82.2 
 
 89.0 
 
 84.4 
 
 69.2 
 
 68.1 
 
 43-4 
 
 21. 1 
 
 Austria Hungary . . 
 
 
 
 O 4. 
 
 2.6 
 
 6 7 
 
 Itrc 
 
 24 C. 
 
 Italy 
 
 O.2 
 
 O.T 
 
 O.C. 
 
 2.O 
 
 C.Q 
 
 17.1 
 
 2C..O 
 
 Russia and Poland. . . . 
 
 O.I 
 
 O.I 
 
 O.2 
 
 1.8 
 
 S- 
 
 15-4 
 
 17.7 
 
 Total 
 
 o-3 
 
 0.4 
 
 I.I 
 
 6.4 
 
 17.6 
 
 48.0 
 
 67.2 
 
 All other Countries. . . 
 
 i7-S 
 
 10.6 
 
 I4-S 
 
 24.4 
 
 14-3 
 
 8.6 
 
 II.7 
 
 Grand Total 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 IOO. 
 
 f Data from Adams and Sumner : Labor Problems, p. 73, and the Statistical Abstract, 
 1006, p. 56. These figures are not exact and not altogether comparable, owing to changes in 
 the immigration year, the distinction of nationalities, and the immigration laws. For the ef- 
 fect of these changes, see Boeckh : The Determination of Racial Stock among American Im- 
 migrants, Publications of the American Statistical Association, December, 1006 ; and Willcox, 
 National Civic Federation Review, November, December, 1906, p. 7.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 65 
 
 are misleading, because they take no account of the large number 
 of immigrants who return to Europe. In the second place, the 
 importance of the number of immigrants depends largely upon 
 its relation to the population of the country; and relative to the 
 population immigration seems to be declining rather than increas- 
 ing. For instance, immigration reckoned in proportion to the 
 population was heavier in the period 1850-1855 than in the period 
 1900-1905. In the next place, the attraction of the city for the 
 immigrant has been exaggerated. While a great majority of the 
 immigrants are forced to locate temporarily in our large seaboard 
 cities, the later and more trustworthy studies indicate that the 
 immigrants are less rather than more disposed to remain perma- 
 nently in the cities than our native population, and that the new 
 immigrants show no greater tendency to stagnate in the cities than 
 the earlier immigrants. Finally, it is to be noted that our immi- 
 gration laws regarding the exclusion of diseased, criminal, im- 
 moral, feeble-minded, and indigent persons are constantly becoming 
 stricter and their administration more efficient. In addition to 
 the plainly undesirable classes just noted, Chinese laborers have 
 been excluded since 1882, aliens under contract to take up par- 
 ticular work since 1885, and anarchists since 1903. 
 
 Surveying the whole history of immigration, three general con- 
 clusions may be drawn which must be fully considered by those 
 engaged in the solution of the present problem. 
 
 (i) We have, as a people, shown a marvelous ability to assimi- 
 late rapidly people of diverse races, tongues, and religions, amal- 
 gamate them and stamp them with the characteristic qualities of 
 the American. Even at the close of the eighteenth century, about 
 one fifth of the population spoke some other language than Eng- 
 lish as their mother tongue, and probably one half of the popula- 
 tion were of other than Anglo-Saxon blood. The heterogeneous 
 character of the population is illustrated by the fact that nine of 
 the men most prominent in the early history of New York repre- 
 sented as many different nationalities. (2) We have failed, how- 
 ever, to amalgamate the negro and the Chinese; the incidental 
 feature of a dark skin creates especially difficult problems; and 
 it is this fact which makes the suggested exclusion of Japanese
 
 66 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 laborers worthy of serious consideration. The high qualities of 
 the Japanese, their industry, intelligence, and native refinement 
 make them in many respects the most desirable kind of immi- 
 grants; but it is conceivable that they might come to this country 
 in sufficient numbers to create a problem similar in character and 
 gravity to the negro problem; and if investigation show that there 
 is real probability of such a result, they should be excluded, even 
 though the danger be attributable to race prejudice of the natives 
 rather than the clannishness and exclusiveness of the Japanese 
 themselves. (3) In the main, however, the traditional policy of 
 this country has been "to improve rather than to check immigra- 
 tion," and the burden of proof is upon those persons who would 
 restrict immigration by arbitrarily limiting the number of immi- 
 grants. 
 
 Natural Resources. Next to the character of the people with 
 which this continent has been stocked, the most powerful factor 
 in shaping the economic development of the United States has 
 been its enormous natural wealth. With a territory (excluding 
 Alaska and our insular possessions) more than three fourths as 
 large as all Europe, indented, particularly on the eastern coast, 
 with a large number of good harbors, intersected by internal water- 
 ways that make communication cheap and easy, endowed with 
 water power that in the opinion of one authority is probably "more 
 valuable than those of all other lands put together," marked by 
 every variety of climate and soil, covered in many places, at least 
 originally, with magnificent forests, and liberally stocked with 
 almost every variety of mineral wealth, it is not surprising that at 
 the present time the United States "leads the world" in the pro- 
 duction of iron and steel, cotton, coal, coffee, gold, silver, dairy 
 products, corn, wheat, lead, lumber, tobacco, petroleum, and hogs. 
 It would be strange, indeed, with the vast mineral and agricultural 
 resources at our command, if we did not "lead the world" in 
 many things. 
 
 Of the 2,972,584 square miles of territory in continental United 
 States, about three fourths at one time or another has belonged to 
 the central government. The possession of this vast common treas- 
 ure by the United States has played an important part in digni-
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 67 
 
 fying and strengthening the federal government. But the lavish 
 alienation of the public lands in endowing free schools, subsidiz- 
 ing railways, and other internal-improvement companies, and in 
 providing free homes for the landless, has been an even more po- 
 tent factor in hastening our economic development; even though 
 it has led, as has been said with some justification, "to the ravish- 
 ment rather than the development of our natural resources." The 
 public domain and its disposition are discussed at some length 
 in a later chapter, but one aspect of this subject the part which 
 free land has played in our economic development is so vitally 
 important that it requires special notice at this point. 
 
 While it was not until the passage of the Homestead Act in 
 1862 that land could be legally acquired without cost by simple 
 occupation and cultivation, it is practically true to say that since 
 the seventeenth century any enterprising citizen, by the exercise 
 of a minimum amount of industry and frugality, could secure a 
 homestead large enough to support himself and family. This op- 
 portunity offered to the artisan a free choice between wage ser- 
 vice and farming, constantly depleted the ranks of mere laborers, 
 operated to keep wages at least as high as the earnings of a " no- 
 rent" homestead, and kept fresh and vigorous that sturdy feeling 
 of independence that has been the distinguishing mark of the 
 American workingman. By 1904, for instance, the national gov- 
 ernment had given away, under the Homestead and Timber Cul- 
 ture Acts, 106,240,464 acres of land; and in addition to this, 
 278,001,612 acres had been sold at less than cost, that is, at less 
 than the cost of acquisition, management, survey, patenting, and 
 the like. 
 
 How long the public lands will hold out it is impossible to say. 
 Notwithstanding the fact that the national government is dispos- 
 ing of its lands at the rate of from fifteen to twenty million acres 
 a year, there is still left if we count Alaska almost as much 
 territory as we have alienated since the adoption of the Constitu- 
 tion. Much of this is worthless or unavailable; but irrigation and 
 dry farming are constantly reclaiming large districts formerly re- 
 garded as worthless, and the railways and some of the Western 
 states still possess large quantities of ordinary farming land which,
 
 68 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 fortunately, they are willing to sell at low prices. All in all, 
 we are tempted to say, there is still enough cheap land to exert in 
 the West that influence upon industry, wages, and the distribution 
 of wealth generally which has come to be the distinguishing 
 mark of the American social economy. But this is a matter of 
 dispute. 
 
 Fifteen sixteenths of the population reside in the eastern 
 half of the United States, and in the East land has become costly, 
 trade and manufactures taken together have outstripped agricul- 
 ture, and a large majority of the people lack the inclination and 
 necessary training, even if they possessed the courage and energy 
 to avail themselves of the cheap land of the West. Whatever 
 the amount of this cheap land, its importance has diminished and 
 must continue to diminish, as an outlet for the population upon 
 whose economic condition it formerly exerted so salutary an influ- 
 ence. Considering the population as a whole, the conclusion seems 
 irresistible that we have reached, if indeed we have not already 
 passed, the parting of the ways; and the assistance that in the 
 past free land rendered in maintaining wages and restraining the 
 evil tendencies of the modern system of capitalistic production 
 must in the future be secured from other sources. The distinc- 
 tive Americanism of the past was generated, as has been said, in the 
 performance of our national task "of winning a continent from 
 nature and subduing it to the uses of man"; 1 it was a product 
 of the frontier. But the frontier has now disappeared. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. What peculiar characteristics mark the economic stages of the United 
 States ? 
 
 2. Is the pastoral stage through which the people of our Great Plains have 
 passed essentially different from the pastoral stage through which the people 
 of Israel passed ? 
 
 3. Enumerate the great sectional struggles which have disturbed the 
 United States. Why does radicalism accompany the frontier? 
 
 4. Has the frontier and the work of settlement left a permanent impress 
 upon the American people? Of what kind? 
 
 5. How rapidly is the population increasing at the present time? Are the 
 richer or poorer classes multiplying more rapidly ? Can you state the reason ? 
 
 1 Bogart, Economic History of the United States, p. i.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 69 
 
 6. What are the distinctively economic factors of the negro problem? 
 
 7. When did the immigration problem first alarm residents of this 
 country? What charges are directed against the "newer immigrants "? 
 
 8. Have we shown an ability to assimilate all kinds of immigrants? 
 What has been the historical policy of this country toward immigration ? 
 
 9. What part did the public domain play in bringing about and preserv- 
 ing the Union? in maintaining wages? 
 
 10. How does the growing size of the country modify the influence 
 exerted by free land ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BOGART, E. L. Economic History of the United Stales. Contains bibli- 
 ography. 
 
 BRUCE, P. A. Economic History of Virginia. 
 
 COMAN, KATHERINE. The Industrial History of the United States. Con- 
 tains bibliography. 
 
 COMMONS, J. R. Races and Immigrants in America. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Studies in t)ie Evolution of Industrial Society. 
 
 EMERY, H. C. " Economic Development of the United States," in The 
 Cambridge Modern History, Vol. 7, Chap. XXII. 
 
 LIBBY, O. G. " The Geographical Distribution of the Vote of the Thirteen 
 States on the Federal Constitution," 1787-1788, Bulletin of the Uni- 
 versity of Wisconsin, Economics, Political Science, and History Series, 
 Vol. i, No. i. 
 
 McMASTER, J. B. A History of the People of the United States. 
 
 McVEY, F. L. Modern Industrialism, Part I, Chap. III. 
 
 SEMPLE, ELLEN C. American History and its Geographical Conditions. 
 
 SHALER, N. S., Ed. The United States of America. 
 
 TURNER, F. J. " The Significance of the Frontier in American History." 
 Fifth Yearbook of the National Herbart Society. First edition in 
 Report of the American Historical Association, 1893, pp. 197-227. 
 
 WEEDEN, W. B. Economic and Social History of New England.
 
 CHAPTER VI 
 
 THE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
 
 (Continued) 
 
 IN the preceding chapter attention was confined to certain fun- 
 damental and peculiarly American conditions which have influ- 
 enced the economic development of this country. They form the 
 background and setting of the picture. When we come to fill in 
 the details, however, the general effect is very similar to that pro- 
 duced by the description of English industrial development given 
 in Chapter IV. There are differences, of course, differences 
 important enough to make this separate discussion of American 
 economic evolution necessary. But, on the whole, it is surpris- 
 ing how rapidly we have developed the industrial maladies and 
 economic problems of the old world. 
 
 Mercantilism in America. In the American colonies, as in 
 England itself, the Industrial Revolution was preceded by a period 
 in which trade and industry were subject to minute regulation by 
 the government. Bounties were freely offered in several colonies 
 for the manufacture of leather, iron, paper, silk, and cloth; land 
 grants were made and taxes remitted particularly in the support 
 of the iron industry; and in order to encourage the home manu- 
 facture of shoes, for instance, the General Court of Massachusetts 
 in 1640 commanded that every hide "be sent to a tannery under 
 penalty of a, 12 fine," while "leather searchers" were appointed 
 to see that the law was obeyed. 
 
 This early colonial regulation was restrictive as well as protec- 
 tive. In the New England colonies, in the seventeenth century, 
 laws were repeatedly passed prohibiting idleness, fixing the hours 
 of labor, and prescribing rates of wages, with appropriate penal- 
 ties for workmen who took or employers who paid more than the 
 
 70
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 71 
 
 legal rate. In the Boston Town Records of 1635, for instance, 
 we find this resolution: " That Mr. William Hutchinson, Mr. Wil- 
 liam Colborne and Mr. William Brenton shall sett pryces upon all 
 cattel, comodities, victuals and labourers and Workmen's W 7 ages 
 and that noe other prises or rates shalbe given or taken." * But 
 the restrictive laws, in general, failed dismally. The abundance 
 of cheap land and the independent spirit generated by the pioneer 
 life prevented the enforcement of obnoxious colonial laws, and 
 eventually led the colonists into armed resistance against the re- 
 strictive legislation of the English government. 
 
 English Colonial Policy and the Navigation Acts. In accord- 
 ance with mercantilist views of colonial relationships, English 
 statesmen of this period looked upon a colony as a community 
 which was to supply raw materials for the industries of the mother 
 country, secure its manufactured goods from the mother country, 
 and so far as trade with the rest of the world was concerned, buy 
 and sell through the mother country. In accordance with this 
 general policy, England gave bounties for the production in 
 America of raw materials such as flax, indigo, naval stores, barrel 
 staves, and the like, but restricted manufacturing proper by 
 prohibiting, for instance, the erection of mills for slitting or rolling 
 iron, and furnaces for making steel and fettered our commerce 
 in a variety of ways. It is unnecessary to enter into the details of 
 this conflict, which is familiar to every student of American his- 
 tory. The English laws were not so severe as might be inferred 
 from our brief statement of their nature and purpose; they were 
 laxly enforced; and it is to be remembered that England encour- 
 aged some industries while she attempted to destroy others. Eng- 
 lish colonial policy of this period was not so much malicious as 
 mistaken. The important points for us are these: that it did 
 not seriously hamper the development of American industry in gen- 
 eral, while it did strengthen and stimulate in the American peo- 
 ple that spirit of individualism which the industrial opportunities 
 of the new world and the frontier conditions of the time combined 
 to create. As a consequence the new nation, created in 1789, was 
 
 1 Governor Winthrop's Journal, printed at Hartford, 1790, p. 188; reprint 
 of 1853, PP- 377-38i-
 
 72 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 pledged to the doctrine of individual liberty, and its constitution 
 contained specific guarantees of personal freedom not only in 
 matters political, but in industrial and social relationships as well. 
 
 American Industries in 1776. When the Revolutionary War 
 broke out, American industry was still in a primitive stage. The 
 extractive industries were, relatively, the most advanced. Large 
 quantities of lumber and timber products were exported to Eu- 
 rope; the fisheries were in a prosperous condition; and shipbuild- 
 ing had reached a really remarkable stage of development, in 
 1775 "nearly one third of the tonnage afloat under the British 
 flag had been built in American dockyards." Agriculture, how- 
 ever, was carried on in the most wasteful and unscientific way, 
 owing to the cheapness and fertility of the soil; and manufacturing 
 was still in the household stage. In the Middle and New England 
 Colonies spinning and weaving, the manufacture of shoes and food 
 products, were carried on within the home; and, in fact, the typi- 
 cal farm household of this period constituted almost an independ- 
 ent economic unit, raising or making what its occupants consumed, 
 and buying little save salt and a few necessary iron implements. 
 Of manufacturing for sale and export, however, there was little 
 worth mention. The absence of adequate means of transport was 
 largely responsible for this state of affairs. The roads were little 
 more than widened Indian trails. Some years later, when con- 
 ditions were considerably improved, the roads were still so poor 
 that " Madison spent a week going from New York to Boston by 
 stage, while the cost of cartage of a cord of wood for a distance 
 of twelve miles was three dollars." Agriculture, however, was the 
 dominant industry of the country. In 1787 less than one eighth 
 of the working population was engaged in manufactures, fishing, 
 navigation, and trade combined. 
 
 The Industrial Revolution in America. The Industrial Revo- 
 lution was sudden, and in its consequences momentous in America 
 as well as in England. The Revolutionary War, by interrupting 
 trade with Europe, threw the American people upon their own 
 resources: goods that had hitherto been imported had now to be 
 manufactured at home; a large number of new industries sprang 
 up rapidly; and the idea became prevalent that the new nation
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 73 
 
 must make itself industrially as well as politically independent of 
 the old world. The state governments endeavored to foster the 
 new industries by protective tariffs, and this policy was later con- 
 tinued, in a moderate form, by the federal tariff act of July 4, 
 1789. Prizes were offered by various societies, and even by cer- 
 tain state governments, for the introduction of the new machines 
 and methods which were revolutionizing industry in England. 
 Attracted by one of these offers, Samuel Slater, "the father of 
 American manufactures," who had been apprenticed to a manu- 
 facturer of cotton machinery, and was particularly familiar with 
 Arkwright's machines and processes, came to this country in 1 789, 
 and in the following year started the first cotton factory at Paw- 
 tucket, Rhode Island. 
 
 The factory system secured its first real foothold, however, be- 
 tween 1806 and 1815, when the Non-Intercourse Acts, the Em- 
 bargo, and the War of 1812, by suppressing trade with Europe, 
 forced the American people to do their own manufacturing, and 
 turned large amounts of capital, which had previously been em- 
 ployed in trade and shipping, into manufactures. The growth 
 during this period of isolation was extraordinary. In 1804 only 
 four cotton mills were in operation. "In 1807 there were fifteen 
 cotton mills running 8000 spindles and producing 300,000 pounds 
 of cotton yarn annually. In 1811 there were eighty-seven mills 
 operating 80,000 spindles, producing 2,880,000 pounds of yarn 
 per year and employing 4000 men, women, and children. In 1815 
 500,000 spindles gave employment to 76,000 persons, with a pay- 
 roll of $15,000,000 per year." l It is hardly necessary to add that 
 when resumption of peace with Great Britain opened the new 
 American industries to the fierce competition of the older English 
 manufacturers, increased protection was granted in the tariff acts 
 of 1816, 1824, and 1828. A little later, in the Middle Atlantic and 
 New England states, the period of factory production had fully 
 arrived. A separate class of wage earners was appearing, who 
 were especially appealed to by new arguments concerning wages 
 in the tariff discussions; workingmen's parties were organized; 
 strikes and trades unions multiplied, and the latter were combined 
 
 1 Coman, Industrial History of the United States, p. 181.
 
 74 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 into municipal and state federations; in the thirties and forties 
 radical reformers linked the "white slaves" of the North with the 
 negro slaves of the South and worked for the abolition of both 
 "wage and chattel slavery"; the factory town and the city slum 
 became recognized economic conditions, and the dangers of the 
 latter were multiplied by the heavy immigration after 1845. By 
 the middle of the nineteenth century the Industrial Revolution 
 was in full sway, and the economic triumph of modern capitalism 
 was assured. 
 
 As might be supposed, the Industrial Revolution produced far 
 less suffering and want in the United States than in England. 
 The evils attributable to the Industrial Revolution in England 
 were of two kinds. One arose from the rapidity and magnitude 
 of the industrial change itself; the other was due, not to the change, 
 but to the system under which the new industry was conducted 
 the system of capitalistic industry working in a regime of practi- 
 cally unregulated competition. In our country the evils resulting 
 from transition alone were slight. Our manufacturing industries 
 were scarcely started when the spinning jenny, the power loom, 
 and the steam engine were introduced, and so almost from the 
 beginning the factory system seemed the natural one. Thus, the 
 change which in England was a revolution was in America an 
 evolution, a process of construction with little destruction. And 
 for a time even those evils inherent in the system itself were miti- 
 gated and disguised by the immense natural wealth of this country, 
 the ease with which land could be obtained, and the unusual mo- 
 bility of our working people, which permitted them to take quick 
 advantage of the unusual opportunities open to them. 
 
 But, as will appear in the following pages, these ameliorating 
 agencies served only to check and delay, not to destroy, the evil 
 possibilities of the new industrial system. As free land has be- 
 come less and less abundant, the wage earners of the East have 
 had forced upon them conditions of life which have kept down, 
 although they have not absolutely lowered, their standard of life. 
 Extremes of wealth and alienation of social classes have become 
 so great as to arouse the apprehension of all thoughtful men. 
 Labor riots that call for military interference testify to the fact
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 75 
 
 that we have not escaped, that in the future we can hope less and 
 less to escape, the friction that accompanies all unfraternal re- 
 lations among men. We have been greatly blest in that we have 
 escaped the worst results so long. 
 
 The Development of Agriculture. The presence and power 
 of those economic forces which softened the asperities of the new 
 industrial system in America are revealed in a particularly strik- 
 ing way in the history of American agriculture. In England, it 
 will be remembered, the changes in agriculture intensified the 
 evils of the industrial revolution, led to the consolidation of small 
 farms into large landed estates, and put the actual business of 
 farming largely into the hands of tenants. In the United States, 
 however, practically none of these tendencies has shown itself at 
 least, not in an alarming form. There is a constant migration 
 from the country to the city, to be sure, but this is in no sense 
 due to the consolidation of farms. Thus between 1870 and 1900 
 the proportion of all breadwinners (persons ten years of age and 
 over gainfully occupied) engaged in agriculture fell from 47.6 to 
 35.6 per cent. On the other hand, more persons are still employed 
 in agriculture than in any other branch of industry; and owing 
 to the opening up of old Indian reservations for farm settlement, 
 the constant alienation of the public domain, and the breaking 
 up of Southern plantations and "bonanza farms." the number of 
 farms seems to have increased quite as rapidly as the general 
 
 population. 
 
 / 
 
 The great improvement which has taken place in agricultural methods 
 and machinery enables the relatively smaller farm population to satisfy the 
 demand for agricultural produce even more completely than in the past. 
 That is to say, the machine power introduced into farming has more than 
 taken the place of those persons and their descendants who have abandoned 
 agriculture. It has been estimated, for instance, that in 1895 it actually 
 required only about 120,000,000 days' work to produce the nine principal 
 farm crops of that year, whereas, had they been produced by the methods 
 and machinery of 1850, at least 570,000,000 days' work would have been 
 required. 1 
 
 1 H. W. Quaintance, "The Influence of Farm Machinery on Production and 
 Labor," Publications of the American Economic Association, Third Series, Vol 5, 
 No. 4, pp. 27-29.
 
 76 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Notwithstanding the improvement of farm methods and ma- 
 chinery, the agricultural industry shows no real tendency to assume 
 a capitalistic form. The average farm of to-day is smaller than it 
 was fifty years ago, and although it represents somewhat more 
 capital, the increase of the capital investment is not great, is much 
 less, in fact, than the increase in the wealth of the average individ- 
 ual. Moreover, a majority of American farmers own the farms 
 they cultivate, and the statistics indicate that it is still compara- 
 tively easy for an enterprising farm laborer to rise to the status 
 of tenant and from that condition into the ranks of the farm pro- 
 prietors. 1 
 
 Manufactures. In agriculture, as we have seen, the passage 
 of time has not brought about a highly capitalized form of indus- 
 try, the typical farm represents only a small investment and is 
 tilled by its owner, there is no sharp distinction between employees, 
 unions of wage earners are practically unknown, and passage from 
 the wage earning to the employing class is still comparatively 
 easy. In manufactures, practically all these conditions have been 
 reversed since the end of the eighteenth century. And it is the tone 
 of the manufacturing industry rather than that of agriculture 
 which represents the keynote of the modern economic movement, 
 because agriculture is constantly decreasing while manufacturing 
 and allied industries are constantly increasing in relative im- 
 portance. At the beginning of the last decade of the eighteenth 
 century, seven eighths of the working population were employed 
 in agriculture, and the manufactured products of the coun- 
 try were valued at $20,000,0x30. Half a century later, in 1840, 
 77.5 per cent of the breadwinners were employed in agriculture, 
 16.5 per cent in trades and manufactures alone, and the products 
 of the manufacturing industries were valued at $483,278,215. 
 Fifty years later, in 1890, 35.7 per cent of the workers were 
 in agriculture, 24.4 per cent in manufacturing and mechanical 
 pursuits, and the manufactured products were valued at 
 
 'Tenancy seems to be increasing in the United States, but the authorities differ 
 in their interpretation of the phenomenon, some regarding it as a favorable and' 
 others as an unfavorable sign. This and other questions touched upon in the 
 preceding paragraphs are discussed at greater length in a later chapter.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 77 
 
 $9,372,437,283. In 1905, to cite the latest figures, the value of 
 the products had reached the enormous sum of $16,866,706,985. 
 
 The change in the character of the industry has been even more 
 striking than its growth and expansion. In the first place, ma- 
 chinery and capital have become increasingly prominent. In 
 1850, for instance, $556 worth of capital was invested for each 
 wage earner, while in 1900 the average amount of capital per 
 wage earner was SiSso. 1 In the second place, the organization of 
 the industry has changed, so that the individual owner and ordi- 
 nary partnership are rapidly being replaced by the corporation. 
 At the beginning of the nineteenth century, corporations, though 
 not unknown in commerce and banking, were very uncommon in 
 the manufacturing industries. In 1905, incorporated companies 
 employed 70.6 per cent of the wage earners and manufactured 
 73.7 per cent of the goods produced in all the manufacturing 
 industries. 
 
 This change in organization has been a powerful factor in de- 
 stroying the personal relation between the owners of capital and the 
 wage earners who man their plants, and has thus helped to widen 
 the growing breach between capital and labor. It has also con- 
 tributed greatly to the concentration of industrial control. Law 
 and custom in this country have combined to make the small 
 stockholder in the largest corporations a virtual nonentity so far 
 as practical participation in the management of the corporation 
 is concerned; and the individual or clique of "insiders" who 
 own a bare majority of the stock rule the business despotically. 
 Incorporation, then, instead of introducing a greater measure of 
 real industrial cooperation and thus democratizing industry, has 
 too frequently turned out to be an ingenious device by which en- 
 ergetic promoters borrow or secure the spare savings of the com- 
 munity on the most flexible terms and with a minimum of respon- 
 sibility. The corporation thus, while it appeared to be diffusing 
 the ownership of industry, has in reality worked toward the con- 
 centration of industrial control. 
 
 1 Owing to variations in the definition of "capital" and other similar changes, 
 the statistical comparisons made in this and the preceding paragraph are not very 
 accurate, and are to be accepted as illustrations rather than measurements.
 
 78 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Other forces, moreover, have been working toward industrial 
 concentration, the most powerful of which, perhaps, has been ex- 
 cessive competition. For many decades in this country the unre- 
 stricted competition of rival manufacturers made them almost 
 Ishmaelites in their business relations with one another. Tied 
 down to their large investments of fixed capital, they were com- 
 pelled to stand and fight without quarter. In every such war 
 the number of combatants tends to decrease. As old rivals are 
 killed off, the successful acquire greater skill and greater power 
 in the conflict. With the passage of time greater and greater 
 equipment is required to give any hope of a successful struggle, 
 and some of the contestants, learning prudence from the struggle, 
 combine to increase their fighting power. The inevitable result, 
 whether through simple survival of the fittest or through combi- 
 nation, is a marked increase in the sixe and importance of the in- 
 dustrial unit. Between 1900 and 1905, for instance, the number 
 of establishments in the factory industries increased only 4.2 per 
 cent, but their capital increased 41.3 per cent, and the value of 
 their products 29.7 per cent. In many of our most important in- 
 dustries the number of establishments is actually decreasing. In 
 the manufacture of agricultural implements between 1880 and 
 1905, to take a single illustration of the many that might be cited, 
 the number of establishments decreased from 1943 to 648, while 
 the capital grew from $62,109,668 to $196,740,700, the wage earn- 
 ers from 39,580 to 47,394, and the value of the products from 
 $68,640,486 to $112,007,344. There are industries, of course, in 
 which no such consolidation has taken place, but they are unim- 
 portant in comparison with those in which it has. The extent to 
 which the giant industry and large-scale production have come 
 to dominate our manufacturing industries in the year 1905 is 
 shown in the following table, which will repay careful study. Es- 
 tablishments of the largest size, i.e. those whose annual output 
 exceeds $1,000,000, constitute less than i per cent of the number 
 of establishments, but manufacture nearly 40 per cent of all the 
 goods. Nearly three fourths of the wage-earners are employed in 
 industries having a capital of more than $ 100,000 each.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 79 
 
 o 
 
 o^ 
 
 U i 
 
 g! 
 
 c 
 
 i>^ 
 
 1 
 
 z 
 
 j, 
 
 Q 
 
 
 
 
 Jf 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 Ov 
 
 un 
 
 
 M 
 
 Z 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 vcT 
 
 IO 
 
 q 
 
 
 % 
 
 ~j_ 
 
 
 vo" 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 r-. 
 
 ^ ^ 
 
 V. 
 
 n 
 
 to oo 
 
 f^ 
 
 M 
 
 to O 
 
 . 
 
 M 
 
 O 
 
 q; 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 ^- 
 
 oo 
 
 8 to 
 M 
 TJ- 
 
 O 
 
 o" 
 
 n 
 
 10 4 
 
 t? 
 
 4 
 
 -T 
 
 t 06 
 CO f*5 
 M 
 
 O 
 
 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 M 
 
 
 O 
 
 ^. 
 
 
 vO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 
 v> 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 U 
 
 8 
 
 
 
 w? 
 
 
 X 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 ' 
 
 
 jj- 
 
 3 
 
 0_ 
 
 
 
 qv 
 
 Q\ 
 
 
 
 
 ~- 
 
 ^~i 
 
 
 O 
 
 H 
 
 b 
 
 1 
 
 M 
 00 
 
 rO 
 
 ON 
 10 OO 
 
 t q 
 
 o~ 
 
 ^ 
 
 00" N 
 
 cc" 
 
 
 
 
 06" 
 vO ro 
 
 B 
 
 * 
 
 
 6 
 
 ^J. 
 
 
 t 
 
 w 
 
 CTJ to 
 
 ^ 
 
 6s 
 
 q M 
 
 8 
 
 z 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 8 
 
 < 
 
 X 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 N 
 
 
 
 
 ro 
 
 
 
 a 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 
 (ft 
 
 
 
 V> 
 
 
 
 
 in 
 
 
 
 
 ON 
 
 
 
 
 
 -T 
 
 
 
 
 S 
 
 8 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 8 
 
 
 0* 
 
 H 
 P 
 
 8 
 
 M 
 
 N 
 
 M 
 
 o 
 
 10 00 
 
 q 
 
 ro 
 
 ^ ^ 
 
 
 N 
 
 tC 
 
 W Tf 
 
 W 
 
 <j> 
 
 *-^ 
 
 CH 
 
 ^^ ro 
 
 * N * OO 
 
 ^ * 
 
 OC 
 
 <^5 ^O 
 
 'j 
 
 ci 
 
 1 4 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 W 
 
 ^- M 
 
 C4 ^ 
 
 m 
 
 I-I 
 
 M 
 
 Ov 
 
 M 
 
 O "i 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 O^ 
 
 *~~ 
 
 
 Ox 
 
 f*5 
 
 
 
 o 
 * 
 
 B 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 "? 
 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 i 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 f) 
 
 if' 
 
 
 J 
 
 i/-, 
 
 
 00 
 
 i-i 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 vO 
 
 o 
 
 ^ 
 
 to 
 
 ^ 
 
 to t>. 
 
 o" 
 
 M 
 
 ^ oo 
 
 oo" 
 
 O 
 
 --c 
 
 vo" 
 
 B 
 
 
 - 
 
 C5 
 
 r^ 
 
 "i 4 
 
 o\ t> 
 
 S 
 
 ti 
 
 ^ 4 
 
 
 r^; 
 
 1 to 
 
 8 
 
 < 
 
 f 
 
 
 M 
 
 5- 
 
 CC 
 
 
 o" 
 
 e< 
 
 
 M 
 IO 
 
 * 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 <^' 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 IO 
 
 
 J 
 
 
 vO 
 
 M 
 
 
 s- 
 
 X 
 
 Q 
 
 P4 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 vO 
 
 c<; 
 
 
 TJ- 
 
 M 
 
 
 *"!. 
 
 H 
 
 en 
 
 tf> 
 
 vO 
 
 M 
 
 M 
 
 I? 
 
 VO" M 
 
 ^ 
 
 vq 
 
 M 
 
 O^ IO 
 
 o" 
 
 o 
 
 6 
 
 10 ^ 
 
 M M 
 
 8 
 
 _i 
 
 
 *"" 
 
 
 to 
 
 O 
 
 M 
 
 1 
 
 
 M 
 
 M 
 
 
 \0 
 M 
 
 
 | 
 
 
 
 v? 
 
 M 
 
 IO 
 
 
 !>. 
 
 
 
 
 f 
 
 
 5 
 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 vO 
 
 n 
 
 o" 
 
 
 6\ 
 
 o> 
 
 
 Tt 
 
 j 
 a 
 
 1 
 
 vO 
 
 
 O 
 
 n" 
 
 P 8 
 
 ^ 
 
 O 
 
 
 
 q 8 
 
 
 
 8 
 
 |s 
 
 
 I 
 
 M 
 
 
 oo M 
 
 to 
 
 W 
 
 
 to 
 
 t 
 
 
 
 
 4 
 
 
 W 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 ' 
 
 
 v> 
 
 
 <s 
 
 & 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 Iri 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 < 
 
 "c 
 
 
 
 
 
 lishments Numbe 
 
 1 
 
 
 il Amount 
 Per cent 
 
 Earners Number 
 Per cent 
 
 s Amount 
 
 "c 
 
 
 U 
 
 Expenses Amour 
 Per cent 
 
 f Materials Amou 
 
 
 
 
 of Products Amt 
 Per cent 
 
 
 
 J3 
 
 
 fl 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 4> 
 
 
 
 0) 
 
 i 
 w 
 
 
 'a. 
 
 ri 
 U 
 
 bo 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 y 
 i 
 
 1 
 U 
 
 
 I
 
 8o OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Recently the movement toward large-scale industry has taken 
 on another phase. In addition to concentration or centralization 
 of industry, we are now having a rapidly increasing integration 
 of industry. Large business concerns are finding it profitable to 
 carry on under one management several closely related industries. 
 For illustration, take the case of the United States Steel Corpora- 
 tion. Here we have united under one management the American 
 Bridge Company, the American Sheet Steel Company, the Ameri- 
 can Steel Hoop Company, the American Steel and Wire Company, 
 the American Tin Plate Company, the Federal Steel Company, 
 the Lake Superior Consolidated Iron Mines, the National Steel 
 Company, the National Tube Company, and the Carnegie Steel 
 Company. Of the last itself, Mr. Charles M. Schwab says, in his 
 testimony before the Industrial Commission (Vol. XIII, p. 448) : 
 "The Carnegie Company were large miners of ore mined all 
 the ore that they required themselves, to the extent of over 
 4,000,000 tons per year. They transported a large percentage of 
 it in their own boats over the lakes; they carried a large percent- 
 age of it over their own railroad to their Pittsburg works, and 
 manufactured it there, by the various processes, into a great vari- 
 ety of iron and steel articles I think perhaps a larger general 
 variety of steel articles than almost any other manufacturing con- 
 cern." 
 
 Transportation and Railways. The industrial concentration of 
 which we have been speaking does not necessarily lessen competi- 
 tion at all. It merely gives the business into the hands of increas- 
 ingly powerful rivals among whom competition may be all the 
 more bitter because of the size of the contestants. But in the 
 principal transportation industries time has amply demonstrated 
 that another rule prevails: competition has utterly failed to pro- 
 tect the consumer, and the progress of consolidation has operated 
 to emphasize and strengthen the inherently monopolistic character 
 of the industry. 
 
 The history of transportation in this country since the estab- 
 lishment of the Union falls into three stages. The "turnpike 
 period" extends from 1790, the year in which the first turnpike 
 was constructed, until 1816, when steam navigation upon the Ohio
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 8l 
 
 River became fairly regular. The second stage, the "river and 
 canal period," ends with the panic of 1837, and is marked particu- 
 larly by the introduction of steam travel on the Hudson (1807), 
 the Ohio, and Mississippi rivers (1808 to 1817) and the opening of 
 the Erie Canal in 1826. The last stage, the "period of the railway," 
 extends from about 1840 to the present time. Of course, in con- 
 trasting these periods, it is not meant to suggest that canals were 
 not built before 1790, or that turnpikes are not important at the 
 present time. As a matter of fact, a canal was built in Orange 
 County, New York, as early as 1750; and there are few economic 
 needs of greater importance at the present time than the improve- 
 ment of our roads. These "periods" merely indicate the kind of 
 transportation facilities which at different times have been most 
 prominent in the minds of the people. 
 
 In the development of the railway, certain approximately defi- 
 nite stages may also be distinguished. Between 1830 (when the 
 first railway the Baltimore and Ohio was opened for traffic) 
 and 1840, the railways were short, local lines used in large degree 
 to supplement or piece out the rivers and canals. In the next 
 period, 1840 to 1870, many new roads were built, and the process 
 of "linear consolidation" the linking together of local com- 
 panies into through trunk lines began. By 1869 both the New 
 York Central and the Pennsylvania had effected through connec- 
 tions with Chicago. In the same year, the completion of the Cen- 
 tral and Union Pacific railways linked the Pacific Ocean with the 
 eastern railways, and the continent was spanned. 
 
 The period between 1870 and 1890 is marked by three striking 
 developments. First, it was a period of feverish expansion: the 
 railway mileage of the country increased from 52.000 to 160,000 
 miles, more than 200 per cent. Secondly, the completion of sev- 
 eral through routes from the Atlantic seaboard to Chicago brought 
 about a period of destructive competition, which led to discrimina- 
 tion and rebating in through traffic and the overcharging of local 
 or non-competitive traffic. "Wherever competition appeared, 
 discrimination followed; and in the scramble for business the 
 stronger shippers were favored at the expense of the weaker. 
 Where there was no competition the public felt that they were
 
 82 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 being oppressed by a monopoly, to make up for sacrifice rates 
 elsewhere a feeling which was intensified by the absentee own- 
 ership of the western roads." l Thirdly, this condition of demor- 
 alization led to a double reaction. The railways sought to re- 
 strain competition by the creation of pools and traffic agreements, 
 while the people sought to protect themselves through legislation 
 and the creation of railway commissions. The Federal or Inter- 
 state Commerce Commission was established in 1887. 
 
 The last period, from 1890 to the present time, has been marked 
 by an unprecedented amount of consolidation and combination 
 among competing roads, and by a general acceptance of the 
 truth that the railway industry is inherently monopolistic and 
 must be subjected to public control. Thus, at the same time that 
 the control of the magnificent railway system of this country 
 greater in extent than all the railways of Europe combined has 
 fallen into the hands of seven or eight groups of men or "inter- 
 ests," dominated by a number of men small enough, some one has 
 said, to sit about the same table, the people themselves have per- 
 fected administrative machinery strong enough, it is hoped, to 
 hold the great monopoly in check. Complete monopoly and effect- 
 ive public control are being perfected at the same time, and 
 with this dual consummation there closes a great epoch in eco- 
 nomic thought and public policy. The new Interstate Commerce 
 Act of 1906 is a public recognition of the fact that the old prob- 
 lem of private competition versus public regulation has given way 
 to the new problem of public regulation versus public ownership. 
 
 It would be almost impossible to exaggerate the part which transportation 
 agencies, and particularly the railways, have played in the economic develop- 
 ment of this country. Ours is a country of "magnificent distances," and 
 because of this fact, it was particularly necessary that superior means of 
 communication and transportation should be early introduced, if the country 
 was to be held together. After the Revolutionary War there was real danger 
 that the settlers west of the Alleghanies would be completely alienated. 
 Washington was quick to realize this fact. "The Western settlers," he wrote 
 to the governor of Virginia, shortly after the Revolutionary War, " stand as it 
 were upon a pivot. The touch of a feather would turn them any way. They 
 have looked down the Mississippi until the Spaniards, very impoliticly, I 
 
 1 H. C. Emery in The Cambridge Modern History, Vol. 7, p. 706.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 83 
 
 think, for themselves, threw difficulties in their way ; and they looked that 
 way for no other reason than because they could glide gently down the 
 stream, without considering, perhaps, the difficulties of the voyage back again, 
 and the time necessary to perform it in ; and because they have no other means 
 of coming to us but by long land transportations and unimproved roads." 
 
 This danger was averted by the building of the Cumberland Road, the 
 introduction of steam navigation on the Ohio, and the completion of the Erie 
 Canal. Later it looked as if the use of the Mississippi and other natural 
 avenues of communication would link the Middle West more closely to the 
 South than the northeastern states, thus giving the South a preponderant 
 influence in the inevitable struggle over slavery. This problem, however, 
 was solved by the railways, which, unlike the rivers, ran east and west rather 
 than north and south. The railway was thus a strong factor in the preser- 
 vation of the Union. And since the Civil War, Western settlement has fol- 
 lowed the railroad. It has been the great pioneering agency of the last half 
 century, and is entitled to as much credit as the public land policy for the 
 rapid settlement of the West. 
 
 In the development of our transportation facilities, however, the State has 
 been from the very first an active partner of private enterprise. Not only 
 has the State built roads, canals, and railways of its own, but it subsidized 
 the private companies which engaged in similar enterprises, with prodigal 
 liberality. Of the total state debts $170,806,187 in all contracted prior 
 to 1838, $60,201,551 were chargeable to canals, $42,871,084 to railways, 
 $52,640,000 to banks, $6,618,868 to roads, and $8,474,684 to miscella- 
 neous objects. After the panic of 1837 there was little direct construction 
 by the State of internal improvements, but national, state, and local govern- 
 ments vied with one another in assisting private companies by exemptions 
 from taxation and by grants of land, money, and credit. How much these 
 subsidies amounted to we do not know, but the aggregate must have been 
 enormous, as appears from the statistics of land grants. " During the twenty- 
 one years between 1850 and 1871, at which time land grants were discontin- 
 ued, more than 159,000,000 acres were placed at the disposal of railroad 
 corporations by the federal government and 55,000,000 by the state govern- 
 ments." * In their origin and genesis, therefore, as well as in their essential 
 nature, the railways are quasi-public institutions. 
 
 The Labor Movement. In the preceding pages we have seen 
 how capitalistic industry under a regime of free competition passed 
 from an earlier period of cut-throat rivalry to a later period of com- 
 bination amounting in many cases to monopoly. A similar phe- 
 nomenon is discernible in the labor movement. At the beginning 
 of the nineteenth century there were probably less than a dozen 
 
 1 Cf. Bogart, Economic History of the United States, pp. 195, 308, passim.
 
 84 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 trades unions in the United States, and we actually know of the 
 existence of only one. Between 1825 and the panic of 1837, how- 
 ever, they multiplied rapidly, and efforts were made to unite the 
 scattered "locals" of separate trades into broader national unions, 
 and to confederate the unions of different trades into municipal 
 and district federations. These efforts were only partially suc- 
 cessful, however, and it was not until after 1850 that permanent 
 national unions were established, and not till the organization 
 of the Knights of Labor in 1869 that a fairly permanent national 
 federation was created. The Knights of Labor reached the zenith 
 of its power about 1886, and since the panic of 1893 its place has 
 been gradually taken by the American Federation of Labor, with 
 which most American unions, except the Railway Brotherhoods 
 and the socialistic unions west of the Mississippi River, are affili- 
 ated. In 1893 tne membership of the American Federation of 
 Labor numbered about 250,000. By 1906 it had grown to ap- 
 proximately 1,444,200. These figures give some idea of the strik- 
 ingly rapid growth of trades unionism in the last fifteen years. As 
 the membership of the American Federation of Labor is usually 
 understated, and as there are probably from 500,000 to 700,000 
 members in organizations not affiliated with the American Fed- 
 eration, we conclude that the aggregate membership of American 
 labor organizations at the close of the year 1906 amounted to 
 about 2,300,000 persons, mostly men. 
 
 There are thus at least five periods distinguishable in the history 
 of American trades unionism: the germinal period, 1789-1825; the 
 revolutionary period, 1825-1850, so called because of the close con- 
 nection in this period between trades unionism and more radical 
 reforms such as socialism and cooperation; the period of nation- 
 alization, 1850-1865; the period of federation, 1865-1893; and 
 the period of collective bargaining, 1893 to the present time. We 
 speak of the present epoch as the period of collective bargaining 
 because it is only in recent years that employers and the general 
 public have recognized that the trades union is here to stay, and 
 must be regarded as an irrepressible, permanent institution with 
 which many employers of labor must bargain, whether they like it 
 or not.
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 85 
 
 The avowed aim of the trades union is a complete combination 
 of all the workers in a given occupation or industry. The Broth- 
 erhood of Locomotive Engineers, for instance, probably counts 
 among its members more than 90 per cent of all the locomotive 
 engineers in North America, although there are few trades 
 which are so completely organized as this. With the passage of 
 time, moreover, the trades unions have made increasing use of 
 the monopolistic principle of the closed shop the principle which 
 leads union men to refuse to work with nonunion men, and which 
 finds expression in the trades-unionist's new commandment: " Thou 
 shall not take thy neighbor's job." Very recently several authori- 
 tative court decisions have held that labor combinations, particu- 
 larly national or international combinations, are contracts or 
 agreements in restraint of trade, and as such are illegal under the 
 federal or state anti-trust acts. This is but official recognition of 
 the fact that the forces which have led to the rapid development of 
 trades unionism since the Industrial Revolution are the same forces 
 which explain industrial combination and consolidation. The 
 anti-trust acts need amendment: not all combinations in restraint 
 of trade, but only unreasonable combinations, should be prohibited. 
 
 The development of powerful combinations in the labor world 
 has engendered a counter movement among the employers, which 
 expresses itself concretely in the modern employers' association. 
 Such organizations are not new; we have record of such an associa- 
 tion among the master shoemakers of Philadelphia in 1789. But 
 in recent years these associations have become permanent, formal, 
 and aggressive. They fight the labor organizations with their 
 own weapons, matching the lockout against the strike, the black 
 list against the boycott, and the "labor bureau" against the "un- 
 fair list" with which the reader of trades-union journals is familiar. 
 Most of the employers' associations, like most of the trades unions, 
 have associated themselves for common action in a large national 
 federation, the Citizens' Industrial Association of America, with 
 which, in December, 1903, there were affiliated sixty national em- 
 ployers' associations, sixty-six state and district associations, and 
 three hundred and thirty-five local or municipal associations of 
 employers.
 
 86 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The bitter conflict between organized labor and organized capi- 
 tal has forced the State, in the interest of industrial peace, to 
 inaugurate "Wage Boards" and Boards of Arbitration and Concili- 
 ation. Some of these, such as the New Zealand Court of Arbitra- 
 tion, are empowered to enforce their awards upon employers and 
 employees; while others, like the Canadian and some of the 
 American State Boards of Arbitration, have no power to settle 
 disputes authoritatively, although they may make "compulsory 
 investigations" and publish their finding as to the equities of the 
 case. These and similar topics, however, are reserved for more 
 detailed discussion in a later chapter. 
 
 State Regulation of Industry. The growing interference of 
 the State in the conflict between capital and labor brings us natu- 
 rally to the general subject of the State in relation to industry. 
 When the American colonies were planted, mercantilism was the 
 dominant political philosophy ; but, as we have seen, mercantil- 
 ism gave way to a philosophy of individualism in the eighteenth 
 century, under the combined influence of the reaction against the 
 English Navigation Acts, the natural antipathy of a frontier com- 
 munity to legal restraint, the philosophy of Locke, and in a minor 
 degree the teachings of the French physiocrats. The triumph of 
 individualism, as a philosophical system, came at the critical pe- 
 riod when our State and federal constitutions were in the making, 
 and it thus became intrenched in the organic law of the nation, 
 giving constitutional sanction to the doctrine of laissez-faire, and 
 establishing a constitutional guarantee of freedom oj contract, in ac- 
 cordance with which adult men were left "free" to work as long 
 as they "pleased" (or were compelled), for whatever wages they 
 were "pleased" (or forced) to accept. Under the influence of 
 these doctrines, for instance, our courts have annulled such whole- 
 some regulations as laws prohibiting payment of wages in store 
 orders, and statutes limiting the hours of labor of men in bake- 
 shops, or other exhausting occupations. Decades of experience 
 have amply proved that the average wage earner is too weak to 
 protect himself against many evils; but our constitutional law 
 has made it exceedingly difficult for the State to protect him. For- 
 tunately, however, the American people have a fashion of bend-
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 87 
 
 ing their constitutional law to fit the facts, not blinding them- 
 selves to the facts by worshiping the law; and in recent years 
 the Supreme Court of the United States has progressed so far as 
 to sanction a state law restricting the hours of labor of men in 
 underground mines and smelters, although many of the state 
 Supreme Courts are far less enlightened. 
 
 It is impossible to show in detail how the free trade and indi- 
 vidualistic tendencies of the Revolutionary period gave way to a 
 constantly growing programme of State interference. The doctrine 
 of laissez-faire was never adapted in its entirety, and year by 
 year we have moved farther and farther away from it. State in- 
 terference began with the adoption of a tariff act in 1789, "for 
 the support of the government, for the discharge of the debts of 
 the United States, and tlie encouragement and protection of manu- 
 factures"; reached almost a maximum in the Embargo Act of 
 1807; showed itself in the policy of internal improvements and 
 State aid to turnpike, canal, and railroad companies; brought us 
 the great mass of labor and factory legislation which has been 
 adopted by so many states since the Civil War; led in turn to the 
 Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 and the Sherman Anti-Trust Act 
 of 1890; and finally culminated in the new Interstate Commerce 
 Act, the National Meat Inspection Law, and the National Pure 
 Food Law. Excessive competition among laborers, which forced 
 them to accept work under conditions destructive of physique and 
 morals, has led to the factory acts, prohibition of child labor, and 
 limitation of the hours of labor of women; excessive competition 
 leading to the adulteration of products and their manufacture 
 under insanitary conditions has given us the Meat Inspection and 
 Pure Food laws; excessive competition among corporations, lead- 
 ing to combination and oppressive monopoly, has brought us the 
 anti-trust acts and regulation through state and national commis- 
 sions. Whether the individualistic character of industrial society 
 endures or disappears, individualists and socialists alike are now 
 agreed that the State must interfere. As a prominent English 
 statesman expressed it, "We are all socialists now," although he 
 merely meant by this statement that the passive theory of govern- 
 ment has been wholly discredited.
 
 88 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Up to the present time State interference has had as its princi- 
 pal object the improvement and preservation of competition. The 
 conscientious manufacturer who would not poison consumers for 
 the sake of swelling his profits, the high-minded employer who 
 would not "sweat" women and children merely to reduce the cost 
 of production, the delicately scrupulous shipper who would not 
 undermine a rival by forcing a common carrier to pay him rebates, 
 all these have suffered as much from the abuses of competition 
 as the general public itself. Industry under the competitive regime 
 is a rough game played for high stakes, and if it is to be played 
 fairly, there must be intelligent rules of the game and an umpire 
 powerful enough to enforce them upon all contestants alike. If 
 the manufacturers of Massachusetts are prohibited from employ- 
 ing children under fourteen years of age while those of South Caro- 
 lina are encouraged to do so, decency is penalized, and the vic- 
 tory goes to the contestant guilty of the greatest number of fouls. 
 
 State interference, as we have said, has had as its principal 
 object the maintenance of competition upon a higher and more 
 wholesome basis. But this has not been its sole object. Our re- 
 cent regulation of public utility companies aims not to bolster up 
 or preserve competition among such companies, but to introduce 
 a substitute for competition; and the strong movement now on 
 foot to modify the Federal Anti-Trust Act is partially based upon 
 a recognition of the possibility that perhaps regulated monopoly 
 may prove on the whole more beneficial than regulated competi- 
 tion. Upon this point we pass no judgment; time alone can tell. 
 Whether it is desirable, whether in the long run it will be possible, 
 to check the monopolistic tendency of the age and thus maintain 
 a competitive as distinguished from a socialistic regime of indus- 
 trial society, may be said to be the supreme economic problem of 
 the twentieth century. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. How do you account for the failure of the early colonial restrictive 
 legislation ? 
 
 2. What was the effect of English colonial policy and the Navigation Acts 
 upon American manufactures? shipbuilding? American political philoso- 
 phy?
 
 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 89 
 
 3. What was the condition of American agriculture in 1776? of manu- 
 factures? shipbuilding? transportation? 
 
 4. Was the Industrial Revolution as important in this country as in Eng- 
 land? Was it attended with as much suffering? Why? 
 
 5. What part has been played by war in the tariff and industrial history 
 of the United States ? 
 
 6. In what respects has the agricultural development of this country 
 differed from that of England ? from that of the manufacturing industry ? 
 
 7. What changes have taken place in the organization of manufacturing 
 industries in the last century? 
 
 8. What are the principal causes and effects of industrial concentration? 
 
 9. What is the difference between industrial concentration and integra- 
 tion? between large-scale production and monopoly? 
 
 10. W 7 hat stages are distinguishable in the history of transportation and 
 railways in this country? 
 
 11. What part did the State play in the development of railways? Is 
 railway consolidation a recent phenomenon? 
 
 12. What movement has the development of trades unionism elicited from 
 employers? from the State? 
 
 13. How did the doctrine of non-interference secure such a strong foothold 
 in American constitutional law? What has been the principal object of 
 State interference up to the present time ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 (See also References for Chapter V) 
 
 BISHOP, J. L. History of American Manufactures. 
 
 BRYN, E. W. Progress of Invention in the Nineteenth Century. 
 
 Census Reports. Tenth Census, Agriculture, p. 131. Twelfth Census, 
 
 Manufactures, Part I, Chap. II, I-VI, XVII, XXXIX. 
 DEVVEY, D. R. Financial History of the United States. 
 HADLEY, A. T. Railroad Transportation, its History and its Laws. 
 JOHNSON, E. R. American Railroad Transportation, and Ocean and 
 
 Inland Water Transportation. 
 
 RABBENO, UGO. The A merican Commercial Policy. 
 SCMNER, W. G. History of Banking in the United States. 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Tariff History of the United States. 
 WEBER, A. F. The Growth of Cities in the Nineteenth Century. Columbia 
 
 Studies in History, Economics, and Public Law, Vol. II. 
 WELLS, D. A. Recent Economic Changes.
 
 
 BOOK II 
 
 PRINCIPLES AND PROBLEMS
 
 PART I 
 
 INTRODUCTION 
 
 CHAPTER VII 
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 
 
 IN political economy many of the technical terms employed are 
 often misunderstood because the same words a.re used in ordi- 
 nary speech with inconsistency and confusion. We have often to 
 choose between the alternatives of being inconsistent and of vio- 
 lating current usage. The present chapter is devoted to a defi- 
 nition of some of the fundamental notions in political economy. 
 
 The statement is sometimes made that economics is a mere 
 bread-and-butter science, and this charge is not without some 
 foundation, since the science studies men in their endeavor to 
 make a living, but it would be an error to suppose that we are 
 concerned with only the sordid aspects of human nature. This 
 is apparent if we enumerate the motives which impel men to 
 acquire wealth. 
 
 Motives in Economic Activity. (i) There is, in the first 
 place, the endeavor to satisfy one's strictly personal wants, giving 
 rise to the struggle for food, shelter, comforts, amusement, etc. 
 These things are wanted for their own sake, because of the pleas- 
 urable effect which they produce upon the individual acquiring 
 them. We have here, in short, the motive of self-maintenance 
 and development. (2) But every normal individual feels such a 
 degree of affection for certain other people that he is also anxious 
 for their maintenance and development. Striving for the wel- 
 fare of others is a second motive which impels men to labor for 
 the acquisition of material things, and in many cases is more effec- 
 tive as a spur to endeavor than the first. A man will hold him- 
 self to the daily grind more persistently when he feels some one 
 
 93
 
 94 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 is dependent upon him than when he is standing alone. (3) A 
 third motive is the desire to gain the esteem of one's fellows. 
 This motive may take the form of an endeavor to do one's part 
 and to be deserving of the companionship of the class of people 
 whom we admire. But much of our wealth acquisition is motived 
 by the hope of impressing our fellows with a sense of our own 
 importance, to show that we are successful, admirable, enviable. 
 When the income permits, old coats are discarded, not because 
 they cease to give protection, nor because they have become aes- 
 thetically objectionable, but because the wearers wish to make a 
 favorable impression upon other people. Half the pleasure of 
 owning fine houses comes from the fact that most people do not 
 have them. This motive is not always a conscious one, since 
 our standards of beauty or propriety may themselves have been 
 the result in part of this desire for distinction. Now that bi- 
 cycles are within the means of workingmen, it is no longer fash- 
 ionable to ride these machines. 
 
 Somewhat similar to the desire for distinction is (4) the desire 
 for power. Men like to dominate and command their fellows, 
 and this want may be satisfied by means of the dollar as well as 
 with the sword; hence our Napoleons of Finance, Captains of 
 Industry, and Railway Kings. 
 
 (5) Again, the desire for activity for its own sake may be men- 
 tioned. Enforced idleness is as painful as prolonged labor, ex- 
 cept to the degenerate. This desire may result in the production 
 of goods, but more commonly it requires the use of goods that 
 have been produced, as, for example, the implements of athletic 
 exercise. Finally, (6) religion or the ethical impulse may be an 
 important factor in controlling the economic activity of the indi- 
 vidual. Observe, for instance, the difference in the history of 
 communistic experiments in which religious feeling has been 
 strong and those in which it has been weak. 
 
 In this discussion the use of the word "motive" must not be 
 taken to mean that all of the economic life of the individual is a 
 consciously rational one, in which pleasures are balanced against 
 pains in such a way as to secure the maximum surplus of satis- 
 factions. Man is, it is true, a rational being, and as such pursues
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 95 
 
 definite lines of action under the influence of conscious motives; 
 but he is also a creature of instincts and habits, and much of the 
 economic activity of the individual has to be interpreted as the 
 working out of instinct and habit. We speak, for example, of 
 such things as the "instinct of workmanship," the "habit of in- 
 dustry," the "habit of saving," and the like. The foregoing 
 analysis of the motives in economic activity is, however, broad 
 enough if we remember that "pleasure" is something that is not 
 always consciously sought, but is often to be understood as the 
 result of the functioning of inherited instincts and acquired 
 habits. 
 
 Utility. As a result of these motives, human beings are striv- 
 ing for the possession of certain things. These we call goods or 
 utilities. To understand the meaning of the term "utility" in 
 economks, we must recall the central fact of our science, that eco- 
 nomics is a science of man. Goods may be of interest to chemistry 
 and physics merely as things, but they have no significance what- 
 ever in economics until they come into relation with man. That 
 fact in man which reflects upon things a new character and makes 
 them goods is the fact of human wants. Anything that is capable 
 of satisfying a human want is a good or a utility. 
 
 We need here to guard against a misunderstanding which the 
 word "utility" sometimes suggests. There is a tendency to con- 
 found it with the idea of benefit, and to suppose that articles are 
 useful just in proportion as they are beneficial. But in economics 
 these two ideas cannot be taken as identical. Utility is the power 
 to satisfy wants, not the power to confer benefits. Cigars are as 
 useful in the economic sense as bread or books, for all three sat- 
 isfy wants. Economic wants may be serious, frivolous, or even 
 positively pernicious, but the objects of these wants are all alike 
 "utilities" in the economic sense. 
 
 Free and Economic Goods. But it is apparent that the wants 
 we have mentioned are very unlike in character. Air and water, 
 for instance, we seldom think of as things we want at all. We 
 usually have them in abundance and without exertion, so that, 
 though they satisfy wants as vital as any we know, we seldom 
 spend any time thinking about them or our dependence upon them
 
 96 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 These are free goods, that is, goods that exist in quantities suffi- 
 cient to supply all wants for them. Land in a new country is 
 frequently a free good. But the list of things that are free is 
 quickly exhausted. On the other hand, goods that are the ob- 
 jects of exchange are called economic. Economic goods are those 
 which exist in quantities less than sufficient to satisfy all wants 
 for them. Hence, we must economize in the use of them, are 
 willing to undergo sacrifice to obtain them, and usually they are 
 obtained only by exertion. It is, however, their scarcity and 
 not the fact that they have cost labor that makes them economic 
 goods. Land, for example, a free gift of nature, is one of our 
 most important categories of economic goods at the present time. 
 
 Effort. Fortunately, the supply of economic goods can, in 
 most cases, be increased by human exertion applied to the ma- 
 terials of nature; but this exertion, if carried beyond ft certain 
 point, is irksome and has an important effect upon our economic 
 life. If the labor force of the community were unlimited, a 
 great many of the goods which we now use sparingly would be 
 as free as air. Idealists have pictured for us a condition of the 
 future where a few hours' work per day for each individual (an 
 enjoyable means of working off surplus energy) will be sufficient 
 to supply us with all of the goods that we have time to consume. 
 At present, however, most of us find that our consumption is 
 limited by the pain of additional effort. The end of our eco- 
 nomic activity is, therefore, not only to get the greatest amount 
 of satisfaction, but also to minimize the amount of painful labor. 
 
 Waiting. Another fact that persists in our economic life is 
 the necessity for waiting. The people of the United States wish 
 to have the Panama Canal, but they cannot get it without years 
 of waiting. They must spend millions of days of labor with no 
 benefit in return for a long time to come. This waiting has 
 often been called abstinence; but that suggests that the waiting 
 is always painful, which is not true, as we shall see later in dis- 
 cussing the subject of interest. 
 
 Services. Goods have been commonly divided into (i) ma- 
 terial things, such as food, clothes, and books, and (2) personal 
 services, such as the advice of a physician or lawyer.
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 
 
 97 
 
 The advisability of the distinction has been denied, Actors and singers, 
 it has been urged, sell us perishable material things, i.e. light and sound 
 waves of a peculiar kind. A recent writer also considers the distinction con- 
 fusing because it obscures the fact that material things give off services just 
 as human beings do. The piano yields services as does the singer. From 
 this point of view persons are durable economic goods along with cattle and 
 wheelbarrows. But, on whatever ground the distinction is made, it is im- 
 portant to recognize that among the things that contribute to our well-being 
 are some personal services that are so perishable that they must be 
 used with the direct cooperation of some other human being, while in other 
 cases the services are, as it were, stored up in some inanimate material things, 
 and the relation between the producer and consumer becomes an impersonal 
 one. The service of a musician, for example, is personal and must be used 
 the moment it is rendered ; the purchase of a musical instrument, on the other 
 hand, means the purchase in a lump of a long series of uses. 
 
 Personal Qualities as Goods. The central point in our science 
 is the conception of man in his relations to his environment, and 
 hence it does not seem reasonable to include the personal quali- 
 ties of men under the head of goods. Good health and techni- 
 cal skill make a man's services more valuable and assist him in 
 the acquisition of wealth, but they are a part of him rather than 
 of his possessions. It is his services that he sells, and it is these 
 that we have placed under the head of goods. When we con- 
 sider the importance of the priceless heritage which the present 
 generation has received in the shape of knowledge and skill, we 
 might make these a separate category as immaterial goods. 
 
 On this point Professor Marshall says : " German economists often lay 
 stress on the non-material elements of national wealth ; and it is right to do 
 this in some problems relating to national wealth, but not in all. Scientific 
 knowledge, indeed, wherever discovered, soon becomes the property of the 
 whole civilized world, and may be considered as cosmopolitan rather than a 
 specially national wealth. The same is true of mechanical inventions and 
 of many other improvements in the arts of production ; and it is true of music. 
 But those kinds of literature which lose their force by translation may be 
 regarded as in a special sense the wealth of those nations in whose language 
 they are written. And the organization of a free and well-ordered State is to 
 be regarded for some purposes as an important element of national wealth." 
 
 But knowledge does not exist in a disembodied state, and we 
 shall omit nothing and avoid some confusion if we divide all 
 goods into material things and personal sendees.
 
 98 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Wealth. Political economists have frequently called economic 
 goods wealth, thus excluding free goods. Some writers, however, 
 include free goods in the idea of wealth. The truth is, that this 
 term cannot be defined satisfactorily unless we specify whether 
 we are speaking from the individual point of view or from the 
 social point of view. From the individual standpoint, wealth 
 means valuable claims to goods; from the social point of view, 
 we shall regard wealth as an aggregate or stock of goods. This 
 excludes personal services from the category of wealth, for they 
 disappear as soon as rendered, and in an inventory of existing 
 wealth, personal services would not appear. 
 
 Wealth and Income. Wealth refers to the stock of goods on 
 hand at a particular time. Real income, on the other hand, has 
 reference to the satisfaction which we derive from the use of 
 material things or personal services during a period of time. 
 Money income should, perhaps, refer to the value of the goods 
 consumed and services enjoyed, although in popular speech and 
 by many economists the word is used in the literal sense of the 
 net amount of money that comes in, whether it is spent for en- 
 joyable things or is saved. In this book we shall use the term 
 " money income " in the latter sense. 
 
 The Individual and Society. One distinction runs all the way 
 through political economy, and that is the distinction between 
 the social and the individual standpoint. That which is wealth 
 to the individual is often not wealth to society. An individual 
 holding a government bond finds that he can exchange it for the 
 things he wants almost as readily as though it were gold or some 
 other commodity. He recognizes that the paper itself cannot be 
 used directly for any useful purpose, yet he prizes it because it 
 represents an indisputable claim on the services or commodi- 
 ties of other people. If the bond should be destroyed, the holder 
 as an individual would suffer loss, but society as a whole would 
 be neither richer nor poorer, and society, exclusive of the bond- 
 holder, would have gained at his expense. From the social stand- 
 point the bond is not wealth at all, but only an evidence of a legal 
 right to a part of the social wealth. All property rights are sim- 
 ply claims to a part of the social wealth or income. The claims
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 99 
 
 to concrete, material things, such as farms and store buildings, 
 are included by an individual when he enumerates his wealth; 
 the farms and store buildings are social wealth. Again, in mak- 
 ing an inventory of his wealth, an individual would not ordinarily 
 include such an item as the post office, which is public and not 
 private property; but, strictly speaking, the post office is owned 
 jointly with other members of society. A successful patent is 
 frequently looked upon as an item of wealth, but it is simply a 
 means by which the owner gets more from other people in return 
 for his services. If the patent is declared invalid, others gain 
 what he loses (not counting the check to the inventive impulse). 
 Again, "good will" in business is frequently paid for as though 
 it were an economic good, and is wealth from the individual 
 point of view, but it is not social wealth. If a business man loses 
 his established trade, his competitors are the gainers; society 
 as a whole is not affected. This distinction between individual 
 and social wealth, however, is valid only when we look upon the 
 social wealth as composed of concrete material objects. When 
 we are measuring the amount of wealth in dollars, no such dis- 
 tinction can be drawn. To attempt to say how much an item 
 of wealth is worth from the social point of view and how much 
 from the individual point of view, would be futile. The owner 
 of a franchise that is declared invalid suffers financial loss; the 
 community suffers no loss, for the tangible property which yields 
 the enjoyable services is not affected. Here is a valid distinction 
 between the individual and social points of view, but from any 
 point of view it cannot be denied that the selling value of the 
 property has been decreased. 
 
 Wealth and Value. In the preceding paragraphs wealth has 
 been spoken of as consisting of particular things. A lead pencil 
 and the year's crop of wheat are both wealth. How shall we 
 measure the amount of wealth that these objects represent? 
 Since the items of wealth are composed of very heterogeneous 
 objects, we cannot use such units of measure as bushels, pounds, 
 or feet. We must select a measure that has reference to some 
 quality common to all kinds of wealth. This quality is the power 
 to give satisfaction to those who have unsatisfied wants, and a
 
 100 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 measure based upon this quality is value. This is a subject 
 which will be discussed in detail later, the valuation of goods and 
 personal services being the central problem in economic theory. 
 It is sufficient to say at this point that high value in an object 
 implies the existence of important unsatisfied wants which this 
 object is capable of satisfying. Thus, free goods have no value, 
 not because they do not satisfy important wants, but because 
 these wants do not ordinarily go unsatisfied. 
 
 Capital and Other Forms of Wealth. Some material things, 
 as well as personal services, yield satisfaction to human beings 
 directly. From clothes, dwellings, food upon the table, musi- 
 cal instruments, and the like, we derive enjoyment directly. 
 These are consumption goods. Other goods are of service only 
 indirectly. A plow, we say, is useful, but we cannot eat or wear 
 it. It simply helps to produce the things that we can enjoy. 
 Such articles are production goods. 
 
 The distinction is a matter of degree. Even the food upon the table is not 
 quite ready to be enjoyed. It must be handled with knives and forks. 
 This has led some writers to make no distinction between wealth and capital 
 goods. But it has been pointed out that great differences in degree are more 
 important than many differences in kind. The distinction, it may also be 
 noted, is not made on the ground of durability. Consumption goods may 
 be very durable, such as a painting or work of fiction. 
 
 Production goods, again, are divided into capital goods and 
 land. Land is a gift of nature; capital goods machinery, 
 warehouses, raw material, etc. are produced by man. Other 
 differences between these two classes will be discussed later. 
 
 Capital Goods and Capital Value. Capital goods, as well as 
 other forms of wealth, are of such a heterogeneous nature that 
 we cannot measure them by such units as pounds or inches. 
 Here, again, we must select some quality that is common to all 
 of them, which is value, and this can be measured in terms of 
 dollars. Very frequently the value of capital goods is confused 
 with the concrete good itself. A typewriter is a tangible, material 
 capital good; its weight is measured by pounds; its bulk by cu- 
 bic inches; its value by dollars. In this book the word " capital " 
 is frequently used as a short expression for either of the phrases
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 
 
 101 
 
 " capital goods " and " capital value," but it will always be clear 
 from the context which is meant. 
 
 Social and Individual Capital. The individual may include 
 items in an enumeration of his capital which are not capital 
 from the standpoint of society. The landlord who has dwell- 
 ings to let regards them as part of his capital, but from the social 
 standpoint they are consumption goods. We may call such 
 goods acquisitive capital. Again, a street railway may consider 
 its franchise as a part of its capital, but from the social standpoint 
 a franchise is not capital at all, nor even a good, but is simply a 
 right to use the streets in a certain manner. Destroy the fran- 
 chise, and the items of social capital would not be directly les- 
 sened. 
 
 Figure i will make clear these various distinctions: 
 
 Circle A B represents goods. 
 
 Circle AC represents economic 
 goods. 
 
 Circle AE represents producers' 
 goods. 
 
 Circle AF represents land. 
 
 Zone BC represents free goods. 
 
 Zone CE represents consumers' 
 goods. 
 
 Zone DE represents acquisitive 
 capital. 
 
 Zone EF represents social capi- 
 tal. 
 
 FIG. i 
 
 The National Wealth and the National Dividend. Attempts 
 have been made to ascertain the total wealth of a nation. The 
 latest estimate made for the United States by the census authori- 
 ties is given on the following page. 
 
 Such a table is useful, even though it may contain some rather 
 arbitrary estimates, as showing the relative importance of dif- 
 ferent classes of our material equipment. Notice the small total 
 value of the metals used as money and the relatively large value 
 embodied in real property. It is rather surprising that manu- 
 facturing machinery, tools, and implements are worth less than
 
 102 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ESTIMATES OF WEALTH FOR 1900 AND 1904 
 
 FORMS OF WEALTH 
 
 1904 
 
 1900 
 
 Real property and improvements 
 taxed 
 
 $55,510,228,057 
 
 6,831,244,570 
 4,073,791,736 
 844,989,863 
 
 3> 2 97>754,i8o 
 1,998,603,303 
 11,244,752,000 
 
 2,219,966,000 
 
 227,400,000 
 585,840,000 
 123,000,000 
 846,489,804 
 275,000,000 
 
 562,851,105 
 
 1,899,379,652 
 7,409,291,668 
 495,543,685 
 408,066,787 
 
 2,500,000,000 
 5,750,000,000 
 
 $46,324,839,234 
 
 6,212,788,930 
 3,306,473,278 
 749,775,97 
 
 2,541,046,639 
 
 1,677,379,825 
 9,035,732,000 
 
 1,576,197,160 
 211,650,000 
 400,324,000 
 98,836,600 
 537,849,478 
 267,752,468 
 
 402,618,653 
 
 1,455,069,323 
 6,087,151,108 
 
 424,97 ,592 
 326,851,517 
 
 2,000,000,000 
 4,880,000,000 
 
 Real property and improvements 
 exempt 
 
 Live stock 
 
 Farm implements and machinery 
 Manufacturing machinery, tools, 
 and implements 
 
 Gold and silver coin and bullion 
 Railroads and their equipment. . 
 Street Railways, etc. : 
 Street railways . 
 
 Telegraph systems 
 
 Telephone systems 
 
 Pullman and private cars .... 
 Shipping and canals 
 
 Privately owned waterworks. . 
 Privately owned central elec- 
 tric light and power stations 
 All other : 
 Agricultural products 
 
 Manufactured products 
 
 Imported merchandise 
 
 Mining products 
 
 Clothing and personal adorn- 
 ments 
 
 Furniture, carriages, and kin- 
 dred property 
 
 Total 
 
 $107,104,192,410 
 
 $88,517,306,775 
 
 
 our live stock. But great care should be taken in comparing 
 the total wealth as estimated in this and in preceding census 
 valuations and in drawing conclusions as to the significance of a 
 growth in national wealth measured in dollars. 
 
 In addition to the difficulty of getting accurate information 
 on these various items, there are several things to be kept in 
 mind in making use of such an estimate. First, the returns are
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 
 
 103 
 
 made in money, so that fluctuations in the value of money will 
 show a change in the total valuation even if there is no change 
 in the relation between the wants of a community and its goods 
 other than money. Again, free goods are not included in such 
 an estimate. Also, a good deal of public property does not have 
 a money estimate put upon it. Who would attempt to say what 
 our rivers and harbors are worth, and yet why should not these 
 be included in the estimate if our canals are? 
 
 It seems that much that is included in the estimate is wealth 
 from the individual standpoint only, but not from the social, as 
 in the case of the valuation of a business whose value consists 
 largely of patents or monopolistic privileges. In the table above, 
 for example, the value of railways in 1904 was obtained by capi- 
 talizing their net earnings. Is this sum properly included in an 
 estimate of the total amount of wealth in the United States? 
 The inclusion is proper if we are confining ourselves to a state- 
 ment of the sum of the values of property rights, but it is mislead- 
 ing if we wish to show the relative importance of railways and of 
 property in a competitive industry, or if we are discussing rail- 
 ways in relation to the public welfare. A similar line of thought 
 is suggested with reference to land values. Ten years ago we 
 had about the same area and the same quality of land as we now 
 have, so that its high value to-day cannot mean that we are better 
 equipped with natural resources. 
 
 We must be on our guard against attaching improper signifi- 
 cance to estimates of total wealth. Changes in total value are 
 not an accurate index of changes in well-being. It is possible 
 that an increase in concrete material goods will actually decrease 
 the total quantity of wealth measured in dollars. A hundred 
 bushels of wheat at $i per bushel have a higher selling value 
 than two hundred bushels at 40 cents per bushel. If by some 
 magical process all goods could be made free as air, there would 
 be no value whatever. An estimate of the value of our stock of 
 wealth also necessarily omits to take account of personal services. 
 It is obvious also that per capita wealth has a more direct rela- 
 tion to well-being than total wealth. Individual wealth and value 
 connote scarcity; well-being implies abundance. Nevertheless.
 
 104 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 under present conditions, it is probable that an increase in per 
 capita individual wealth, when not due to fluctuations in the value 
 of money, also indicates an increase in well-being. There is no 
 likelihood of our being able to increase the quantity of economic 
 goods to such an extent as to render them free and hence value- 
 less; and, on the other hand, as will be more fully explained 
 later, new wants are constantly developing, and value is at bottom 
 the power to minister to unsatisfied wants. 
 
 The national income is a concept which takes account of the 
 services rendered directly by persons as well as of the material 
 things that are used. The national income, objectively consid- 
 ered, is a gigantic stream of food, clothes, comforts, personal ser- 
 vices, etc., which is used up in the direct satisfaction of wants in a 
 specified period, such as a year, by the millions of individual acts 
 of consumption. Some writers would include also the additions 
 to our industrial equipment, such as new machines; but they 
 may also be regarded as promises of an enlarged future income 
 of society, not a part of its present real income. These two views 
 correspond to the two definitions of income on page 98. 
 
 It is difficult to make an accurate estimate of the national in- 
 come in terms of its money value, and not much confidence can 
 be placed in the estimates that have been made. A reliable cal- 
 culation of this kind would, however, be useful as an index of 
 the maximum gain that might be derived by the mass of the people 
 from agitation for a more nearly equal distribution of wealth. It 
 would be interesting to know what the scale of living would be if 
 the national income were equally distributed. At present we do 
 not know whether a family of five persons would have $800 or 
 $1600 to spend. 
 
 The national income may be looked upon as the national divi- 
 dend, the sum total of good things to be divided among the vari- 
 ous families or individuals. The forces determining the size of 
 this dividend, the manner of its division, and the saneness of its 
 use are the main topics for discussion in political economy, and 
 hence it will be our purpose in subsequent chapters to describe 
 the general tendencies in the consumption, the production, and 
 the distribution of wealth and income.
 
 ELEMENTARY CONCEPTS 105 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Does the following statement agree with the definitions in the text? 
 "The true basis for an estimate of a nation's wealth is to be found in the en- 
 joyments of its members." Hadley, Economics, p. 4. 
 
 2. Are the following wealth : air ? whisky ? a copyright ? Lake Michigan ? 
 skill as a carpenter ? good health ? 
 
 3. Discuss the following : " Among the motives which lead men to accumu- 
 late wealth, the primacy, both in scope and intensity, therefore, continues to 
 belong to this motive of pecuniary emulation." Veblen, Theory of the 
 Leisure Class, p. 34. 
 
 4. State the significance of the following : " A horse is not wealth to us if 
 we cannot ride, nor a picture if we cannot see, nor can any noble thing be 
 wealth except to a noble person." Ruskin, Munera Pulveris, p. 10. 
 
 5. Discuss the following statement : " In 1770 Arthur Young reckoned the 
 income of England to be 120,000,000; in 1901 the income may be roughly 
 set down at 1,600,000,000. Making correct allowances for population 
 and for prices, this growth of income would signify a large increase of com- 
 modities per head ; but would it tell us that we are working and living some- 
 what better than our ancestors?" Hobson, The Social Problem, p. 43. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. III. 
 
 CLARK, J. B. The Philosophy of Wealth, Chaps. I and III. 
 
 FISHER, IRVING. The Nature of Capital and Income, Chaps. I and II. 
 
 HOBSON, J. A. The Social Problem, Book I, Chap. V. 
 
 LESLIE, T. E. C. Essays in Political Economy, Chap. I. 
 
 MALLET, B. A Method of Estimating Capital Wealth from the Estate Duty 
 
 Statistics, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, March, 1908. 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, Book II. 
 RUSKIN, JOHN. Munera Puheris, Chap. I. 
 
 SIDGWICK, HENRY. The Principles of Political Economy, Book I, Chap. III. 
 SMART, WILLIAM. Studies in Economics, Chap. VIII; and Distribution of 
 
 Income, Book II. 
 SPAHR, C. B. The Present Distribution of Wealth in the United States, 
 
 Chap. V. 
 
 VEBLEN, T. B. The Theory of the Leisure Class, esp. pp. 24-34. 
 WAGNER, ADOLPH. Crundlegung der politischen Oekonomie, 3d ed., VoL 
 
 I, pp. 83-135. 
 Special Census Reports, 1907, Wealth, Debt, and Taxation.
 
 PART II 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 CHAPTER VIII 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 Consumption Defined. Consumption in economics means the 
 use of goods in the satisfaction of human wants, which is the pur- 
 pose of a large part of our economic activity, but it is not the sole 
 purpose, since activity is to a certain extent an end in itself. Nev- 
 ertheless, in economic society as it is organized to-day we are per- 
 haps justified in looking upon consumption as the motive force 
 behind production. Wants are so far from satisfied at present 
 that men look for work, not because they seek to be rid of surplus 
 energy, but because they crave the goods which their wages will 
 buy. The power of unrestricted consumption seems to be the 
 prevailing ideal. Industry, furthermore, is organized and con- 
 ducted primarily to satisfy the consumer, not the worker. This 
 fact is the basis of the Consumers' League, which aims to improve 
 conditions of production by asking the consumer to refuse to pur- 
 chase the goods of unfair employers. 
 
 A study of the consumption of wealth falls only partly within 
 the domain of economics, for the use of wealth is a large part of 
 the problem of life. Passing judgment on the standards accord- 
 ing to which the rationality of certain wants is to be measured 
 does not directly concern the economist. 
 
 Productive and Final Consumption. When used without quali- 
 fication, the word " consumption " in economics is commonly taken 
 to refer to the use of goods to satisfy wants directly. But some 
 goods, such as machines and raw materials, are used up in the 
 production of other goods. This we may call productive consump- 
 tion, while that consumption which attains the ultimate goal of 
 
 106
 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 107 
 
 economic activity directly in the satisfaction of wants is final con- 
 sumption. It is now less necessary than it was in the days of Car- 
 lyle and Ruskin to insist that food consumed by laborers is not 
 productive consumption. They consume, not merely for the sake 
 of production, but also for the sake of satisfaction. Man is our 
 final term. 
 
 Human Wants. In the study of human wants as a starting 
 point in economic theory, two facts stand out prominently: the 
 expansion in the number and variety of the wants, and the satia- 
 bility of any particular one of them. As man has progressed from 
 savagery to civilization, the variety of things he desires and even 
 considers necessary to his existence has expanded enormously. 
 His interests become more varied, his capacity to enjoy becomes 
 larger, and he lives a fuller and more complex existence. There 
 are indeed those who would have us "return to nature " and live 
 a simple life, but taking the world as it is, we may assume that 
 there is no limit to the capacity of the community to use more 
 goods. 
 
 But when we turn to the consideration of some particular want 
 by itself, the matter is wholly different. Our nerves grow weary 
 of a repeated stimulus, and any attempt to continue indefinitely 
 the enjoyment of some sensation results in satiation. A phono- 
 graph record grows stale after a number of repetitions. An apple 
 does not always have the same degree of utility for any one of us, 
 van-ing from the highest degree, if we are on the point of starva- 
 tion, to disgust, if a considerable number have just been con- 
 sumed. 
 
 Law of Diminishing Utility. This fact is of fundamental im- 
 portance in the study of economics and has been dignified by the 
 term "the law of diminishing utility." In formal words: The 
 intensity of our desire for additional units of any commodity de- 
 creases as we consume successive portions. It should be observed 
 that an interval of time between the successive acts of consump- 
 tion may permit our nerves to recuperate so that no diminution in 
 the degree of utility is apparent. Again, the increase in a person's 
 stock of an article held for the purpose of exchange, such as money, 
 can cause a decrease in the utility of an additional unit only to the
 
 Io8 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 extent that all of his wants are being satisfied, since such an ex- 
 changeable commodity in reality stands for all commodities avail- 
 able to him. Again, consumption of certain articles may result 
 in the development of new related wants. The amateur pho- 
 tographer, for example, finds that the crude pictures which de- 
 lighted him at first give him less and less pleasure, but his interest 
 in photography may continue to increase because he sees an end- 
 less variety of results to be achieved. 
 
 Different Uses for the Same Commodity. In the preceding 
 paragraph mention was made of the different degrees of intensity 
 of a particular want. The utility of a commodity may also vary 
 because of its capacity to satisfy different wants of varying im- 
 portance. Thus water, first of all, satisfies thirst. The impor- 
 tance of this utility is altogether incalculable, for without it we 
 should die. Then it serves for bathing, a use which certainly 
 seems essential, but one which is far less urgent than the foregoing. 
 If we had to do without one or the other, there is no doubt which 
 we should prefer. Then it serves for washing dishes, clothes, and 
 a multitude of such things, then for sprinkling lawns and streets, 
 then for fountains, artificial ponds, etc. All these uses and many 
 more are economic, because men will and do pay for water to 
 satisfy these wants. 
 
 Marginal Utility. It must be evident, therefore, that to say 
 that a certain thing is a utility is very indefinite. That merely 
 tells us that it is capable of satisfying some want, perhaps impor- 
 tant, perhaps unimportant. We become definite only when we 
 have specified the degree of utility possessed by the commodity. 
 This is commonly called its final or marginal utility, because when 
 we think of a commodity as consumed in successive portions, the 
 present is the last or marginal unit consumed. Marginal utility 
 means simply the importance which is attached to an additional 
 unit of the commodity at the present moment. This individual 
 valuation of a unit of the commodity may be spoken of as its sub- 
 jective value. This is to be distinguished from its market value, 
 or what can be obtained in exchange for the commodity, which is 
 a resultant of many individual valuations. Market value will be 
 discussed in subsequent chapters.
 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 FIG. 
 
 A clearer notion of subjective value (or marginal utility) may 
 be given with the help of Figure i, following. We return to 
 our illustration of water, which we remember had numerous 
 uses of various degrees of importance. We have marked off dif- 
 ferent portions of the base 
 line representing quantities 
 of water available for man's 
 use. The first quantity, ab, 
 is just enough for drinking 
 purposes. Suppose this is 
 all the water to be had. 
 There will be no question 
 of sprinkling lawns or even 
 of bathing under such cir- 
 cumstances. What will be 
 the utility of water? Evi- 
 dently the extent of the service which it renders us, and as this is 
 the preservation of our life we cannot estimate it. We will indi- 
 cate it by the area above the line ab which runs upward indefi- 
 nitely as the curved line fails to close in. What will be the impor- 
 tance of another portion of water at this point of supply ? As this 
 additional portion which we desire is not needed for drinking but 
 for a less important purpose, the subjective value of the water 
 will now depend upon this less-important want. Now suppose 
 we have three portions of water, represented by the lines ab, be, 
 and cd. We now have enough for all our wants, down to sprin- 
 kling the lawn and the street. We are willing to pay something 
 for more water for this purpose, but how much? As much as 
 when we had only water enough to drink ? By no means. The 
 next want on our list is comparatively unimportant, and of course 
 we value an increased supply accordingly. With two or three 
 more portions of water all our wants are satisfied, and water will 
 have for us no value whatever. Its marginal utility will have 
 become zero. As the amount of water is increased, the subjec- 
 tive value falls according to the curved line hi, till finally it touches 
 the base line, where the utility of the water ceases and it has no 
 value at all.
 
 no 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 It should be carefully noted that marginal utility tells us noth- 
 ing about the total subjective value of the whole stock of the com- 
 modity. It refers solely to the present value of an additional unit, 
 or the sacrifice that would be occasioned by the loss of a unit. 
 We cannot get the total subjective value by multiplying the margi- 
 nal utility by the number of units, even though they be all alike. 
 The very term "marginal" tells us that the conception implies 
 successive additions, and the present value of an additional unit 
 tells us nothing definite about the marginal utility at a previous 
 period. If we wish to ascertain the total subjective value of a 
 stock of a commodity, we have simply to treat it as one large unit, 
 and ask what would be lost if it were taken away. By this test 
 all air would be found to have an immeasurable utility, at the 
 same time that the marginal utility, that is, the subjective value 
 of an additional quart, would be nothing. Thus it will be seen 
 that the cause of subjective value is utility under a condition of 
 scarcity; that is, such a limitation of the supply that all wants 
 cannot readily be satisfied. 
 
 The Economic Order of Consumption. What has been said 
 regarding the way in which our individual estimates of the im- 
 portance of a commodity are determined will help to explain how 
 we make our choices in attempting to obtain the largest amount 
 
 la 
 
 Ib 
 
 Ic 
 
 Id 
 
 2 a 
 
 2c 
 
 FIG. 
 
 FIG. 3 
 
 of satisfaction with the income at our disposal. Evidently we must 
 spend each succeeding dollar for purchasing that commodity of
 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 III 
 
 which a dollar's worth will give the greatest satisfaction. Let Fig- 
 ures 2 and 3 show the declining importance of two commodities 
 which an individual is consuming, and suppose that each unit 
 of each commodity costs one dollar. If the individual has ten 
 dollars to spend upon these two commodities, his order of con- 
 sumption will be as follows: he would begin with 2a, but another 
 unit of commodity 2 would give him less satisfaction than a 
 unit of commodity i. Hence, his consumption will continue as 
 follows : 
 
 la, 2b, 20, ib, ic, id, zd, 2e, le. 
 
 In this illustration it was assumed that a unit of each commodity 
 had the same cost. In this case, the unit consumed is always the 
 one that has the largest marginal utility. But where the cost of 
 the units is different, cost must be considered also, and we com- 
 monly do so by asking ourselves whether the thing we are buying 
 is worth as much as other things which could be obtained with 
 the same expenditure. Thus we are constantly abstaining from 
 the further consumption of one thing, not because our wants for 
 it are fully satisfied, but because something else of equal cost 
 appears at that moment to be more important. 
 
 Future Wants. Not all of the goods for which we strive are 
 wanted for present consumption. We recognize that we shall 
 have needs next month or next year, and we attempt to make some 
 preparation for them. These future wants, it is true, usually ap- 
 
 1m 
 
 Ib 
 
 Ic 
 
 Id 
 
 FIG. 4 
 
 Z fit Sf i * C |*^*J _ 
 
 FIG. 5 
 
 peal to us less vividly than if they were present, but we attach a 
 definite importance to them and grade them, and they enter into
 
 112 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 our calculations when we spend money, modifying the order oi 
 our consumption. This will be seen from Figures 4 and 5. Let 
 us suppose that in Figure 4, a, b, c, d, c represent the diminishing 
 importance of successive units of a commodity for present con- 
 sumption, and that Figure 5 shows the importance of similar quan- 
 tities of the same commodity for future consumption. Then la 
 would be consumed first, i.e. in the present. But a second unit 
 now would be less important in this individual's estimation than 
 the saving of a unit for future use. The second unit, therefore, 
 that is consumed would be 20,, and then the order would be as 
 follows: ib, 2b, ic, etc. Thus this individual has saved two out 
 of five units, i.e. 2d and 2b, with the same sort of mental calcu- 
 lation as he would use in deciding to spend a nickel for a peach 
 rather than for a pear. But if some one should ask him to spend 
 his fifth dollar for 20 instead of for ic, he would require some extra 
 inducement to repay him for the loss in enjoyment. It thus ap- 
 pears that a certain amount of saving is done without irksome- 
 ness, which emerges only when the saving is carried beyond a 
 certain point. 
 
 Alleged Present Consumption of Future Products. We often 
 hear of consumption in advance of production. It is said people 
 live on the future. It is frequently argued that during the Civil 
 War we were consuming faster than we were producing. It is 
 alleged that the federal bonds represented the consumption of 
 future earnings. But it must be apparent that it is impossible 
 to consume faster than we produce unless we consume past sav- 
 ings by not replacing worn-out equipment. We cannot eat to-day 
 the wheat or potatoes of to-morrow, nor can we wear coats before 
 they are made. What is alleged can only be true of the individual 
 consumer within the nation, or in case of the nation as a whole 
 when the capital or other wealth of the country is diminishing, 
 whereas during our Civil War it increased. What really hap- 
 pened was this: we as a nation became indebted to some extent 
 to foreigners, and within the nation some of us gained while the 
 rest were losing. Bonds do not represent a present consumption 
 of future wealth, but a special use of productive power for which 
 a government agrees to remunerate its owners in the future. If
 
 CONSUMPTION n-j 
 
 war can be carried on with the aid of bonds, it can, leaving out 
 of consideration what foreigners send us, with a sufficiently per- 
 fect taxing machinery, conceivably always and practically some- 
 times, be carried on without bonds. It is only a question of how- 
 to get hold of the means of producing powder and bullets. War 
 was formerly carried on without bonds; they are a comparatively 
 recent contrivance. Consumption can never anticipate future 
 production for the nation as a whole taken by itself; it can only 
 anticipate future ownership. 
 
 Consumption and Saving. It is difficult to say in practice at 
 what point consumption should stop and saving begin, but the 
 principle itself is clear. So much, and only so much, should be 
 saved as will maintain a maximum final consumption over long 
 periods of time. It is conceivable that the present generation 
 might deny itself everything except the barest necessities and 
 labor to increase the productive equipment to be used in the future; 
 but the next generation could not pursue the same policy, for 
 some one must consume the products of the factories built to-day, 
 otherwise the building of them was wasted effort. 
 
 To provide for old age or for possible accident may be a suffi- 
 cient motive for saving in some cases, but saving is stimulated 
 when the goods saved will bring an increase. It is, therefore, 
 necessary to an extensive saving that the conditions of profitable 
 investment should be provided; and if wealth is to be widely dif- 
 fused, opportunities for investment should be readily available. 
 It is a perceived opportunity to make an investment with proba- 
 bility of increase which stimulates saving above everything else. 
 Another important condition is security. If the investments of a 
 country fluctuate between loss of principal and unreasonable profit, 
 the condition is one to encourage speculation rather than saving. 
 Among the institutions which encourage saving are private 
 property, corporations, cooperative enterprises, savings banks, 
 and insurance. 
 
 Luxury. Luxury is the name of a vague something which 
 
 society has always viewed with a sense of mingled tolerance and 
 
 condemnation. In the first place, it is clear that people ordinarily 
 
 consider as luxuries many things in themselves innocent and de- 
 
 i
 
 114 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 sirable, as silk dresses, jewels, pictures, etc. No one but an ascetic 
 will condemn as wrong in themselves things that appeal to taste 
 and finer appreciations, and yet we feel that the use of such things 
 is often unjustifiable. Second, the popular idea of luxury recog- 
 nizes a difference in persons. We cannot help condemning in 
 one person what we approve in another. Third, we judge luxury 
 differently at different times. There is a continual transfer of 
 articles from the list of luxuries into that of comforts and neces- 
 sities. This transfer is brought about by the consensus of social 
 judgment, and is increasingly acquiesced in by all. So we see 
 that the term " luxury " does not apply to goods of a certain char- 
 acter, but to certain goods in their relation to time and person. 
 For the purpose of discussion, we shall define luxury simply as 
 excessive consumption. But what determines whether consump- 
 tion is excessive or not ? 
 
 The answer to this question depends, first, upon our idea of 
 right living, and second, upon our idea of a just distribution of 
 wealth. The former question we shall not discuss. It is that 
 of the simple life versus the complex and varied life, and may be 
 left to the sociologists, philosophers, and moralists. But what is 
 a just distribution of wealth? In the world's speculation upon 
 this subject, three ideas stand out prominently: (i) equality, 
 (2) product, (3) needs. Let us examine these three bases of 
 distribution. 
 
 The ability of men to use wealth sanely is enormously unequal, 
 and there is no probability that this inequality will soon be re- 
 moved. To distribute wealth equally, therefore, would be to use 
 goods where they satisfied trifling wants or none at all. But in 
 addition to its wastefulness, an equal distribution is further objec- 
 tionable because of the discouragement it might give to the ener- 
 getic members of the community. Would a man continue to 
 work hard if his lazy neighbor received as much as he ? There 
 is only one sense in which we must regard men as equal, and that 
 is that the happiness of one is as important as the happiness of 
 another. 
 
 That wealth should be distributed according to what men pro- 
 duce is perhaps the most widely held idea at the present time,
 
 CONSUMPTION ue; 
 
 sometimes on the ground that it is theirs by natural right, which 
 is fallacious, and sometimes on the ground that such a method 
 of distribution is a cure for laziness. There is, however, great 
 difficulty in applying this test accurately under the complex con- 
 ditions of modern industry. Who shall say what the president of 
 a great life insurance society is producing? How many dollars' 
 worth has a physician produced who has saved a man's life? 
 However satisfactory the test of productivity may be in the case 
 of a man who produces a pair of shoes with his own implements 
 and labor, it fails at many points under modern industrial condi- 
 tions, and its failure has become increasingly apparent with the 
 growth of large-scale production and monopoly. 
 
 Those who are impressed with the difficulty of saying what a 
 man has produced, suggest that we ascertain what he needs. This, 
 it is true, is not capable of exact determination; but any wide 
 departures from justice might be agreed upon by judicial inquiry. 
 Needs are the basis of the distribution within the family. The 
 solidarity of the family demands it, and this is but the epitome 
 and type of the solidarity of society. It is unquestionably in the 
 interest of society that those with the highest capacities should be 
 allowed to attain the fullest development of all their powers, pro- 
 vided these powers are used in the service of humanity. What 
 is necessary to make a man a good citizen? That, according to 
 this third view, is the ultimate test of a just distribution. 
 
 It is not necessary for us to select as a practical programme any 
 one of these tests and wholly reject the others. The first, equal- 
 ity, reminds us that the lowliest human being is to be looked upon 
 as an end, not as a means to the happiness of others; the second 
 is safe and convenient so far as it can be definitely applied; but 
 the final test, so long as we are social beings, will always be that 
 of needs, understanding by "needs," not what the individual asks 
 for, but what is required for a full development of his powers. 
 
 While, then, justifiable consumption will, according to these 
 principles, be exceedingly variable, can any one for a moment 
 claim that such principles now govern consumption? Immense 
 sums are squandered on passing caprices whose satisfaction can- 
 not by any standard be considered necessary. On the other hand,
 
 Il6 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 multitudes of fine natures with keen appreciations and large ca- 
 pacities for development and present enjoyment are left without 
 the means for either. So long as these things exist, so long as a 
 vast amount of the world's wealth is destroyed by vulgar and in- 
 competent consumption which might impart satisfaction of a high 
 order if consumed otherwise, and by others, the moral sense of 
 the world will condemn luxury as a social wrong. 
 
 And what is the excuse for this abuse ? Usually the simple fact 
 of ownership. "It is ours," they say. But for what? Simply 
 because the interests of production require capital to be massed 
 under specialized control. There is no more reason why a mil- 
 lionaire should consume all the income he controls than there is 
 why a philosopher or an artist should withhold from society the 
 satisfactions afforded by his genius. A successful manufacturer 
 once expressed the opinion that a man has the right to put down 
 silk velvet on a muddy crossing to walk on if he is rich enough 
 to afford it. When a man tramples in the mire the fruit of human 
 industry, he tramples with it human rights and humanity, and he 
 should expect humanity to avenge the affront. The right of pri- 
 vate property, like other social institutions, is ever on trial. The 
 obsolete objection is sometimes urged that luxury gives employ- 
 ment to labor. Does not philanthropic and productive expendi- 
 ture do the same? But that is not the question. What comes 
 of the employment? The payment of wages only helps men to 
 get more of existing goods from other persons. That may be 
 good for those workmen individually, but the only way to help 
 society as a whole is to give men useful employment, to aid and 
 encourage them to produce needed goods. Every employment of 
 labor which encourages production of luxuries is a misdirection 
 of social energy, an encouragement to society to spend its money 
 for that which is not bread and its labor for that which satisfieth 
 not. 
 
 Harmful Consumption. We have been careful to avoid the 
 impression that luxury consists in the use of pernicious goods. 
 It is a common query, "Why should I not have this if it does me 
 no harm?" This we have tried to answer in the preceding para- 
 graphs. A luxury may be a positive good in itself, a satisfaction
 
 CONSUMPTION Iiy 
 
 which society may well hope to make general, but it is a good 
 which society cannot yet afford because other and greater wants 
 are yet unsatisfied. But there is another kind of consumption 
 which is objectionable in an entirely different way, not because 
 it is excessive or premature, but because it is harmful in itself. 
 Such are frequently drugs and alcoholic beverages. As we have 
 said before, these wants are as economic as any other, and we 
 have no intention of assuming the function of the physiologist or 
 the moralist in enumerating the evils which come from the con- 
 sumption of certain goods. But in one respect we have a distinct 
 part in this discussion. All production is for the sake of man, 
 and consumption is its final term. But in turn man is the prin- 
 cipal factor in production, and as the consumption of certain 
 goods affects him, the result is necessarily transmitted to the pro- 
 ductive process. Now the consumption of certain goods clearly 
 unfits men for efficient production, lessening bodily vigor, blunt- 
 ing the perception, and these goods the economist regards as harm- 
 ful in the sense of being destructive of human energy. 
 
 Statistics of Consumption. Instructive investigations have been 
 made as to the relative importance of the leading items in the fam- 
 ily budget. The late Ernst Engel, the former distinguished head 
 of the Prussian Statistical Bureau, advanced the theory that it 
 might be possible by a careful study of a sufficient number of 
 family budgets for a period of years to indicate the broad changes 
 in consumption, and thus by a sort of social signal service to pre- 
 dict the coming of industrial storms. Nothing has been so far 
 accomplished along this line, but Engel's tables are interesting. 
 From Table I (page 118) he deduces the following four propo- 
 sitions : 
 
 First. That the greater the income, the smaller the relative 
 percentage of outlay for subsistence. 
 
 Second. That the percentage of outlay for clothing is approxi- 
 mately the same, whatever the income. 
 
 Third. That the percentage of outlay for lodging or rent, and 
 for fuel and light, is invariably the same, whatever the income. 
 
 Fourth. That as the income increases in amount the percent- 
 age of outlay for sundries becomes greater.
 
 n8 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 TABLE I 
 ENGEL'S LAW SAXONY 
 
 ITEMS OF EXPENDITURE 
 
 PER CENT OF THE EXPENDITURE OF THE 
 FAMILY OF 
 
 A Workingman 
 with an Income 
 of from $225 
 to $300 a year 
 
 A Man of the 
 Middle Class 
 with an Income 
 of from $450 
 to $600 a year 
 
 A Man in Easy 
 Circumstances 
 with an Income 
 of from $750 
 to $1000 a year 
 
 i. Subsistence 
 
 62.0 
 16.0 
 
 I2.O 
 
 s-. 
 
 2.O 
 I.O 
 I.O 
 
 I.O 
 
 95-o 
 5- 
 
 55-] 
 18.0 
 
 I2.O 
 
 5-Oj 
 3-5 
 
 2.0 
 2.O 
 
 2-5 
 
 90.0 
 
 IO.O 
 
 50.0" 
 18.0 
 
 12. 
 
 5-o. 
 
 5-5 
 3-o 
 3-o 
 
 3-5. 
 
 85.0 
 
 'S-o 
 
 2. Clothing 
 
 *. Lodging. . 
 
 4. Heat and light 
 
 5. Education, public worship, 
 etc 
 
 6. Legal protection ' . . 
 
 7. Care of health 
 
 8. Comfort, mental and bodily 
 recreation 
 
 Total 
 
 1 00.0 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 
 Subsequent investigations in the United States have confirmed 
 in a general way the conclusions of Engel, but the correspondence 
 is not exact, as will be seen from Table II (page 119), from the 
 reports of the United States Bureau of Labor, summarizing the 
 expenditure of over two thousand families in 1891 and over eleven 
 thousand in 1903. 
 
 A recent careful study of two hundred families in New York 
 gives the following division of expenditures : 
 
 BRANCH OF EXPENDITURE 
 
 AMOUNT SPENT 
 
 PER CENT or TOTAL 
 
 Food 
 
 $367 A2 
 
 A.1 
 
 Rent 
 
 
 
 Clothing 
 
 88 4? 
 
 10 6 
 
 Light and Fuel 
 
 42 J.6 
 
 C T 
 
 Insurance 
 
 12 1Z 
 
 7 O 
 
 Sundries 
 
 147.31 
 
 17.6 
 
 Total 
 
 8*6 2? 
 
 IOO O 
 
 

 
 CONSUMPTION 
 
 The author of this study comes to the conclusion that a "fair liv- 
 ing wage for a workingman's family of average size in New York 
 City should be at least $728 a year, or a steady income of $14. 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 EXPENDITURES OF AMERICAN FAMILIES INVESTIGATED BY THE 
 UNITED STATES BUREAU OF LABOR 
 
 (From the Seventh [1891] and Eighteenth Annual Reports [1903]) 
 
 
 PER CENT OF TOTAL EXPENDITUB 
 
 
 Food 
 
 Clothing 
 
 Rent 
 
 Fuel and 
 
 Miscella- 
 
 
 
 
 
 Light 
 
 neous 
 
 
 1891 
 
 1003 
 
 1891 
 
 1903 
 
 1891 
 
 1003 
 
 1891 
 
 1003 
 
 1891 
 
 1003 
 
 Under $200 
 
 49.6 
 
 5-9 
 
 12.8 
 
 8. 7 
 
 15-5 
 
 16.9 
 
 8.1 
 
 8.0 
 
 14.0 
 
 15-6 
 
 $200 or under 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 $?oo . . . . 
 
 4.4.3 
 
 47.7 
 
 14.3 
 
 8.7 
 
 14.7 
 
 18.0 
 
 7.6 
 
 7.3 
 
 IO 2 
 
 18.8 
 
 wsy*" 
 
 $300 or under 
 
 H-T-O 
 
 *T/ "O 
 
 *t* o 
 
 / 
 
 **T* / 
 
 
 / 
 
 / 
 
 iy..* 
 
 
 $400 
 
 4C 6 
 
 48 I 
 
 I4.I 
 
 IO.O 
 
 1C o 
 
 18 7 
 
 7 O 
 
 71 
 
 18 \ 
 
 16.1 
 
 $400 or under 
 
 o*** 
 
 ^"* - " 
 
 **T* 
 
 
 ij.w 
 
 *"/ 
 
 /" 
 
 * 
 
 10.3 
 
 
 Ss;oo 
 
 4C..I 
 
 46 o 
 
 14.4 
 
 1 1. 4 
 
 1C. -I 
 
 18.6 
 
 6.6 
 
 67 
 
 18.6 
 
 i6<; 
 
 wyw 
 
 $500 or under 
 
 1O * 
 
 t"-y 
 
 *T't 
 
 "*T 
 
 ^J'O 
 
 
 
 "/ 
 
 
 v3 
 
 Sooo - . 
 
 43-8 
 
 46.2 
 
 IS-3 
 
 I2.O 
 
 15-2 
 
 18.4 
 
 6.6 
 
 6.2 
 
 19.1 
 
 17.2 
 
 
 $600 or under 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 STOO 
 
 A.I 2 
 
 1 C. 
 
 le.o 
 
 12 O 
 
 jc e 
 
 18."; 
 
 e 
 
 c.8 
 
 21.6 
 
 IO 4 
 
 V/vw 
 
 $700 or under 
 
 41 * 
 
 too 
 
 *o - y 
 
 i^.y 
 
 1 jO 
 
 **-*o 
 
 J'V 
 
 J " 
 
 
 iy.^ 
 
 $800 
 
 *8 Q 
 
 4.1 4. 
 
 16.3 
 
 ia.c 
 
 ic 6 
 
 18.1 
 
 e.'i 
 
 C.5 
 
 27. 
 
 21.6 
 
 $800 or under 
 
 sr**jr 
 
 41 .-4 
 
 * v *o 
 
 *O'J 
 
 *j-" 
 
 
 J'O 
 
 JO 
 
 o y 
 
 
 $900 
 
 38.1 
 
 41.4 
 
 J5- 1 
 
 13-6 
 
 16.1 
 
 17.1 
 
 5-3 
 
 5- 
 
 25-5 
 
 23.0 
 
 $900 or under 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 $1000 
 
 34-3 
 
 39-9 
 
 1 6.8 
 
 14.4 
 
 14.9 
 
 17.6 
 
 4-7 
 
 5- 
 
 29.1 
 
 23.2 
 
 
 $1000 or under 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 $1 IOO . . 
 
 34-7 
 
 38.8 
 
 '7-5 
 
 i5- r 
 
 IS- 1 
 
 17-5 
 
 4-5 
 
 4-9 
 
 28.1 
 
 23-7 
 
 
 $i 100 or under 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 $ i 200 
 
 70 7 
 
 3.7 7 
 
 16 c 
 
 14 
 
 12.2 
 
 16.6 
 
 ?.O 
 
 4-7 
 
 *6.7 
 
 26.1 
 
 $1200 or over .. . 
 
 J^'l 
 
 28.6 
 
 jl 1 
 36.5 
 
 w*3 
 
 IS-7 
 
 *H-y 
 IS-7 
 
 12.6 
 
 17.4 
 
 o y 
 
 3- 
 
 *? / 
 S-o 
 
 o / 
 40.1 
 
 25-4 
 
 All 
 
 41.1 
 
 43- 1 
 
 15-3 
 
 13-0 
 
 IS-I 
 
 18.1 
 
 5-9 
 
 5-7 
 
 22.7 
 
 20.1 

 
 120 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 a week. Making allowance for a larger proportion of surplus 
 than was found in these families, which is necessary to provide 
 adequately for the future, the income should be somewhat larger 
 than this; that is, from $800 to $900 a year." l 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. If you had four sacks of corn all alike, could you tell which is the 
 marginal one ? 
 
 2. If an individual estimates his present wants as 10, 8, 6, 3, i, and his 
 future wants as equivalent to the present value of 9, 7, 5, 2, o, and if he has 
 $9, and if each want is satisfied with $i, how many dollars will he save? 
 
 3. Give as many expressions as possible that are equivalent to the term 
 "subjective value." 
 
 4. Comment on the following : " Doubtless the best thing to do about them 
 (the spendthrifts) is to do nothing not even to worry about their waste 
 of money. Their waste of money, in fact, is the least silly thing they do, for 
 the money is in constant flux and serves its purpose." World's Work, June, 
 1906, p. 7597. 
 
 5. Comment on the following words of Adam Smith: "Nothing is more 
 useful than water ; but it will purchase scarce anything ; scarce anything can 
 be had in exchange for it. A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any value 
 in use, but a very great quantity of goods may frequently be had in exchange 
 for it." Wealth of Nations, Book I, Chap. IV. 
 
 6. Point out the differences in the tables of consumption statistics quoted 
 in the text. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BOHM-BAWERK, E. VON. Positive Theory of Capital, Book III, Chaps. 3 
 
 and 4. 
 CARVER, T. N. "How Ought Wealth to be Distributed?" Atlantic 
 
 Monthly, 1906, Vol. 97, p. 727. 
 DEVINE, E. T. Economics, Chaps. V and VI. 
 HOBSON, J. A. The Social Problem, Book II, Chap. VII. 
 JEVONS, H. S. Essays in Economics, Chaps. II and III. 
 KELLEY, F. " Aims and Principles of the Consumers' League." American 
 
 Journal of Sociology, Vol. V, p. 289. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, Book III. 
 MAYO-SMITH, RICHMOND. Statistics and Economics, Book I, Chap. II. 
 MORE, L. B. Wage-Earners' Budgets. 
 ROWNTREE, B. S. Poverty, Chaps. VI, VII, and VIII. 
 SMART, WILLIAM. Introduction to the Theory of Value, Chaps. I to VI. 
 Eighteenth Annual Report of the United States Bureau of Labor. 
 
 1 More, Wage-Earners' Budgets, New York, 1907, pp. 208 and 269.
 
 PART III 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 CHAPTER IX 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 Production Defined. Man creates no new matter. Neither 
 the farmer nor the merchant adds one atom to the existing material 
 of the earth. Yet they are both properly called producers because 
 they increase our supply of economic utilities. Production, then, 
 means the creation of economic utilities by the application of 
 man's mental and physical powers to the materials of nature. 
 The act of production can be reduced to the following three opera- 
 tions: (i) changing the form of things, (2) changing their place, 
 and (3) keeping them until such times as they are wanted ; in other 
 words, production adds to the materials of nature, form utilities, 
 lime utilities, and place utilities. It has seemed to some that the 
 farmer is more truly a producer than the manufacturer, and the 
 manufacturer than the merchant; but such is not at all the case. 
 All of these industrial classes help at some stage in the process 
 of getting the materials of nature ready for consumption. The 
 miner gets iron ore from the ground, the manufacturer trans- 
 forms it into stoves, the railway company transports them, and 
 the merchant keeps them until they are wanted. One stage is as 
 essential as another if wants for stoves are to be satisfied. It 
 may well happen that the utilities produced by the merchant 
 could be produced with a smaller expenditure of economic force, 
 and that by a better organization of the factors of production saving 
 could be effected; or it may be that at times the merchant has 
 been able to secure a larger return for a given effort than the 
 farmer, but this is no justification whatever for the popular 
 impression that he is not a productive worker.
 
 122 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Factors of Production. It has been customary to speak of 
 three factors of production nature, labor, and capital. Under 
 nature are included all forces external to man, as the wind, the 
 movement of water, attraction of gravitation, cohesion, etc. Fre- 
 quently these things furnished by nature are called simply land, 
 because, of what belongs to external nature, it is with land that 
 we have principally to do in political economy. 
 
 Labor, as a factor of production, includes human activities of 
 every sort, intellectual as well as physical, which have economic 
 significance. We might better, perhaps, substitute man for labor 
 as the second factor. Labor is supplied by human beings and is 
 different from material goods because it is always connected with 
 a personality. Moral and intellectual qualities increase its pro- 
 ductiveness. Temperance, trustworthiness, skill, alertness, quick 
 perception, a comprehensive mental grasp, all these and other 
 qualities belonging to the soul of man are of paramount impor- 
 tance. Man's mere physical strength in itself is a poor thing, 
 being surpassed by that of the lower animals, but man is far more 
 productive, and even as a slave sold for more than the lower 
 animals. 
 
 Man can get but little from nature with his unaided hands. The 
 instruments which assist him, as we have seen, are called capital; 
 in other words, capital is every product which is used or held for 
 the purpose of producing or acquiring wealth. By this definition, 
 land is evidently excluded from the category. The nation's capital, 
 then, consists of tools, machinery, business buildings, transporta- 
 tion systems, raw material, etc. We may here again caution the 
 reader against confusing these concrete goods with their value. 
 Capital cannot be looked upon as an independent factor of produc- 
 tion, since it is derived from the labor of man applied to nature. 
 This fact has led some persons to say that capital is simply stored- 
 up labor, but this overlooks the important element of time re- 
 quired for production with the aid of capital. When we say that 
 to print a book according to present-day methods requires the co- 
 operation of labor and capital, we do not deny that the type-setting 
 machines and printing presses which are used are themselves the 
 product of other kinds of labor. To substitute capital for labor
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 I2 3 
 
 may seem to be simply substituting one kind of labor for another. 
 But a long time elapses between the digging of the iron ore and the 
 actual using of the machines in printing. Capitalistic production, 
 as distinct from simple hand labor, is merely a different method 
 a roundabout method of applying human labor to the materials 
 of nature. It is this time element which gives rise to the problem 
 of interest to be discussed in a later chapter. 
 
 " Capital is an intermediate product of nature and labour, nothing more. 
 Its own origin, its existence, its subsequent action, are nothing but stages in 
 the continuous working of the true elements, nature and labour. They, and 
 they alone, do everything from beginning to end in bringing consumption 
 goods into existence. The only distinction is that sometimes they do it all 
 at once, sometimes by several stages. In the latter case the completion of 
 each stage is marked outwardly by the appearance of a fore-product or inter- 
 mediate product, and capital has emerged. But, let me ask, is a thing any 
 the less the work of its author that it is not produced all at once, but in in- 
 stallments? If to-day, by allying my labour with natural powers, I make 
 bricks out of clay, and to-morrow, by allying my labour with natural gifts, 
 I obtain lime, and the day after make mortar and so construct a wall, can it 
 be said of any part of the wall that I and the natural powers have not made it ? 
 Again, before a lengthy piece of work, such as the building of a house, is 
 quite finished, it must naturally be at one time a fourth finished, then a half 
 finished, then three quarters finished. What, now, would be said if one were 
 to describe these inevitable stages of the work as independent requisites of 
 house-building, and maintain that, for the building of a house, we require, 
 besides building materials and labour, a quarter-finished house, a half-finished 
 house, a three-quarters finished house ? In form perhaps it is less striking, 
 but in effect it is not a whit more correct, to elevate those intermediate steps 
 in the progress of the work, which outwardly take the shape of capital, into 
 an independent agent of production by the side of nature and labour." * 
 
 It has been customary to distinguish fixed capital, which lasts 
 for a succession of operations, and only a part of the value of which 
 passes over into the product with each use, from circulating capital, 
 which is used up in one act of production. Coal used in a loco- 
 motive is an example of circulating capital; the car in which the 
 coal is hauled is fixed capital. The difference is one of degree only. 
 
 Saving and Capital Formation. From the individual stand- 
 point, saving means the postponement of consumption. To lend 
 
 1 Bohm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital (trans, by W. Smart), p. 96.
 
 124 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 to another, and thus secure a claim on his services for the future, is 
 an act of individual saving, but this does not necessarily result in 
 saving from the social standpoint. An act can be termed social 
 saving only when the total social income in the future will be in- 
 creased thereby. It is conceivable that this might take the form 
 of merely hoarding up finished consumption goods in anticipation 
 of a famine, but that is not the kind of saving that is typical of 
 modern industrial nations. It is true that we frequently produce 
 durable consumption goods which will be used for a long time in 
 the future. The construction of a public library building in part 
 involves social saving. But true social saving may also consist 
 in bettering the industrial equipment of society. To provide more 
 and better machines it is necessary to use some of the labor which 
 might be used to increase our present income. If all of the labor 
 now used in the construction of new milling machinery, ovens, etc., 
 were employed in turning into bread all of the flour we now have 
 on hand, we could doubtless greatly increase temporarily our 
 present income in bread, but it would be at the expense of the 
 future income. Thus the saving which results in the formation 
 of social capital requires two things: (i) abstaining from the 
 largest possible income to-day, and (2) using part of our labor in 
 bettering the industrial equipment. Individual saving, however, 
 itself commonly results in social saving also, as will be explained 
 in a later chapter. 
 
 Production and Sacrifice. Over against the enjoyment re- 
 sulting from wealth consumption lies the discomfort of wealth 
 
 production. Enjoyment, we have 
 seen, grows less and less as the 
 consumption of a particular good 
 is continued, but the irksomeness 
 of producing it, on the contrary, 
 grows greater and greater the 
 
 x longer labor is continued. Let 
 
 FIG. i 
 
 us take the case of Robinson 
 
 Crusoe picking berries. We may represent the diminishing 
 utility of the berries to him by the line ab (Fig. i), and the in- 
 creasing irksomeness of picking them by the line cd. He would
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 I2 5 
 
 not pick more than Ox, because the xih berry costs him just as 
 much pain as it yields him pleasure, and any further continuance 
 of gathering fruit would result in an excess of pain. The degree of 
 utility represented by mx, then, represents at the moment that the 
 xih berry is picked and eaten, both the marginal utility and the 
 marginal disutility, or marginal pain or sacrifice. 
 
 Each of us is continually making such comparisons balancing 
 the pleasure of further consumption against the pain of further 
 production. Many persons who are working eight or ten hours a 
 day could increase their income somewhat by working twelve 
 hours, but the additional discomfort is greater in their estimation 
 than the additional fruits of their labor would be worth. To be 
 sure, much of our economic action goes on unconsciously. We 
 accept a position, considering its advantages and its disadvantages 
 in a general way as compared with the income it yields, but once 
 we enter upon the work, we accept the daily grind as inevitable, 
 and, in spending our income, think not of the pain it causes 
 us, but simply of how we can get the maximum satisfaction 
 from it. 
 
 In discussing future wants we saw that postponing the con- 
 sumption of goods from the present to the future began to be irk- 
 some only after a certain amount of goods had been saved. Under 
 present methods of production, it has just been explained, a large 
 amount of this postponement of consumption is required. Ma- 
 chines must be made, and the result of this labor cannot be enjoyed 
 until these machines have been used up in making finished 
 products. This means that some one must wait for the result, and 
 in many cases this is irksome. Thus production may require, in 
 addition to the pain of labor, the sacrifice of irksome -waiting or 
 abstinence. This is a point which will be discussed further in the 
 chapter on interest. 
 
 Cost of Production and Expense of Production. The preceding 
 paragraphs explain the most fundamental sense in which the term 
 "cost of production " is used, i.e. (i) the subjective cost of painful 
 labor or irksome waiting. But (2) the phrase is commonly used to 
 refer to the expense of production, that is, the number of dollars' 
 worth of labor and capital goods spent in getting an article on the
 
 126 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 market. (3) A third meaning is also found, which may be termed 
 opportunity cost. Let us say that a person is confronted by the 
 alternative of engaging in either of two occupations. He may be 
 either a lawyer or a merchant, but he has not the time to be both. 
 If he chooses to be a lawyer, he sacrifices his opportunity of being 
 a merchant. In some cases this form of sacrifice is not easy to dis- 
 tinguish from the first. If a man is hesitating whether to accept a 
 position requiring nine hours' work per day or one requiring ten 
 hours, shall we think of him as considering the irksomeness of the 
 tenth hour, or the leisure which he would be sacrificing? But 
 where the opportunity that is sacrificed is an occupation or busi- 
 ness, this "opportunity-cost" is simply one way of looking at 
 the fact that we aim to get the greatest possible return for our 
 labor. 
 
 Organization of the Productive Factors. The three factors, 
 land, labor, and capital, must be brought together for purposes of 
 production. In the case of many farmers and small-scale manufac- 
 turers, all three are furnished by the same person, but under our 
 system of private property, a marked differentiation of ownership 
 takes place as industrial development becomes more complex. 
 In a large-scale establishment it is the exceptional case where the 
 majority of the laborers have any share in the ownership of the 
 capital, but generally the owners of the capital are also the owners 
 of the land. In American agriculture, ownership of the land and 
 the capital by the same person is also widespread, but in England 
 at the present time it is the rule that the landowner and farmer are 
 different persons. On the other hand, factories are frequently 
 built upon leased ground, and much land is farmed in America by 
 tenants who furnish their own capital. Separation in the owner- 
 ship of the productive factors and accurate accounting make neces- 
 sary a distinct valuation of the services of each one of the factors. 
 
 The Entrepreneur, or Undertaker. The one who manages a 
 business for himself was formerly called an undertaker, or ad- 
 venturer, but the first word has been appropriated by one small 
 class of business men, and the latter has acquired a new meaning, 
 carrying with it the implication of rashness and even dishonesty. 
 We have consequently been obliged to resort to the French language
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 127 
 
 for a word to designate the person who organizes and directs the 
 productive factors, and we call such a one an entrepreneur; but 
 recently the term " undertaker " has been more frequently em- 
 ployed with this broad general meaning. 
 
 The function of the entrepreneur has become such an important 
 one in modern society that it is often convenient to regard him 
 as a fourth factor in production, distinct from other classes of 
 laborers. He has been well called a captain of industry, for he 
 commands the industrial forces, and upon him more than any 
 one else rests the responsibility of success or failure. A business 
 which has achieved magnificent success often becomes bankrupt 
 when, owing to death or other causes, an unfortunate change in 
 the entrepreneur is made. The prosperity of an entire town has 
 sometimes been observed to depend upon half a dozen shrewd 
 captains of industry. 
 
 Division of Labor. A characteristic feature of the organiza- 
 tion of the factors is what is commonly called a division of labor, 
 but this term suggests a number of related ideas which must be 
 distinguished, (i) We may mention first a separation of occupa- 
 tions, each one being independent of the other, as is shown, for 
 example, in the splitting up of medical work into various special- 
 ties, and again, entirely new occupations are continually appearing. 
 (2) We also find production divided into stages, each one giving 
 rise to a commercial product, but not to a finished consumption 
 good. This becomes clear if we think of the history of almost any 
 article of daily use : the making of bread presupposes the flour and 
 wheat stages. (3) We have in the third place what is most com- 
 monly referred to by the term " division of labor," where the pro- 
 ductive process is divided into minute parts, and one part given 
 to each laborer. The organization of a cotton mill affords an 
 excellent illustration : 
 
 In cotton mills, as in all other textile mills, there are men of skill and ex- 
 perience who superintend or oversee the work in various buildings and in 
 the rooms and yards. These supervisory employees have assistants, and 
 the division of superintendence is carried down to the sections of rooms, so 
 that all sections have their supervisors, known variously as section bosses, 
 section hands, section girls, and third hands. The following list of occupa-
 
 128 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tions will indicate the extent to which division of labor is carried in this 
 industry: alley boys (or girls); bundle boys; filling and roving carriers; 
 belt makers, blacksmiths, carpenters, machinists, masons, painters, steam 
 fitters, and other mechanics, including sometimes electricians and battery- 
 men ; roll coverers ; helpers ; laborers (unskilled) ; bale openers ; picker 
 hands or cotton shakers; lap tenders; card brushers; first and second 
 breaker hands; finisher pickers; card boys; card hands; waste hands; 
 wastemen; card clothiers; card strippers; card grinders; combers; lap- 
 head hands; doublers; drawing -frame tenders ; rail way -head tenders; slub- 
 bers; speeders, fly-frame tenders; jack tenders; rovers; spinners; bobbin 
 boys; yarn pourers; piecer and doffer; back boy; band boys; doublers 
 and twisters ; winders ; yarn untanglers ; spool boys, white spoolers ; warp- 
 ers ; slasher tenders ; size makers ; reel hands ; dye-house hands (with further 
 subdivisions) ; beamers and splitters ; beam carriers ; warp drawers ; harness 
 menders; harness brushers; handers-in; twisters-in; loom fixer; pattern 
 makers; putters-up oi^amples; cloth weavers; weavers of designs; yarn 
 carriers ; smash piecers ; spare weavers ; inspectors ; trimmers. The finish- 
 ing of the cloth is a separate industry. 1 
 
 This form of the division of labor may also exist without the 
 use of complex machinery, as in the slaughtering and meat- 
 packing industry. 
 
 "It would be difficult to find another industry where division of labor has 
 been so ingeniously and microscopically worked out. The animal has been 
 surveyed and laid off like a map ; and the men have been classified in over 
 thirty specialties and twenty rates of pay from 16 cents to 50 cents an hour. 
 The 5o-cent man is restricted to using the knife on the most delicate parts of 
 the hide (floorman) or to using the ax in splitting the backbone (splitter) ; 
 and wherever a less skilled man can be slipped in at 18 cents, i8| cents, 20 
 cents, 21 cents, 22^ cents, 24 cents, 25 cents, and so on, a place is made for 
 him and an occupation mapped out. In working on the hide alone there are 
 nine positions at eight different rates of pay. A 2o-cent man pulls off the 
 tail, a 22^ cent man pounds off another part where the hide separates readily, 
 and the knife of the 4o-cent man cuts a different texture and has a different 
 "feel" from that of the 5o-cent man. Skill has become specialized to fit the 
 anatomy." * 
 
 Advantages of Division of Labor. The advantages of a divi- 
 sion of labor have been enumerated as follows: (i) A gain of time. 
 A change of operations costs time. Less time is also consumed in 
 
 1 From the Glossary of Occupations in the volume on Employees and Wages. 
 Twelfth Census, Special Reports, 1903. 
 
 2 Commons, Trade Unionism and Labor Problems , p. 224, in a chapter appear- 
 ing originally in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XIX, p. i.
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 129 
 
 
 learning one's business, as the labor of each is more simple. 
 (2) Greater skill is acquired, because each person confines himself 
 to one operation. (3) Labor is used more advantageously. 
 Some parts of an industrial process can be performed by a weak 
 person, others require unusual physical strength; some require 
 extraordinary intelligence, some can be performed by a man of 
 very ordinary intellectual powers, and so on indefinitely. Each 
 one is so employed that his entire power is utilized, and work is 
 found for all, young and old, weak and strong, stupid and intel- 
 lectually gifted. (4) Inventions are more frequent, because the 
 industrial processes are so divided that it is easy to see just 
 where an improvement is possible. Besides this, when a per- 
 son is exclusively engaged in one simple operation, he often sees 
 how the appliances he uses could be improved. Workmen have 
 made many important inventions. (5) Capital is better utilized. 
 Each workman uses one set of tools, or one part of a set, and keeps 
 that employed all the time. When each workman does many 
 things, he has many tools, and some are always idle. (6) Finally, 
 where the division of labor results in the simplification of opera- 
 tions, it facilitates the substitution of machinery with mechanical 
 power in place of direct human labor. "It is the largeness of 
 markets, the increased demand for great numbers of things of 
 the same kind, and in some cases of things made with great accu- 
 racy, that leads to subdivision of labor; the chief effect of the im- 
 provement of machinery is to cheapen and make more accurate 
 the work which would anyhow have been subdivided." l 
 
 Effects upon the Worker. The effect of the introduction of 
 machinery upon wages will be discussed in a later chapter, but 
 here some attention should be given to the effect of division of 
 labor and machinery upon the life of the worker. It is frequently 
 said that when labor is rendered simple it loses both its attractive- 
 ness and its educational value. A man can like his work when 
 he manufactures a whole watch, bearing the impress of care and 
 skill, but who can like the mere routine of feeding material into 
 some machine ? A workingman becomes a mere cog in a great 
 mechanism, driven at a certain speed, day after day, with no 
 
 'Marshall, Principles of Economics, 4th ed., p. 334. 
 K
 
 130 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 further interest in the result of his labor than that it is the source 
 of his daily wage. But much may be said on the other side. To a 
 large extent the heaviest labor is done with mechanical appliances, 
 and those movements which are very simple and regular are precisely 
 the ones which are likely to be taken over by machinery, leaving 
 to human beings the work which requires intelligence and skill. 
 
 "Looked at broadly, is the average work of a laborer in a machine industry 
 less dignified, less agreeable, less humanizing than it was before the industry 
 reached the machine stage ? From the nature of the question, it is danger- 
 ous to dogmatize, because neither the affirmative nor the negative is capable 
 of being demonstrated. The negative view seems to rest mainly upon the 
 assumption that it is more dignified to be occupied with a great many purely 
 mechanical operations than with a very few. The old-fashioned shoe- 
 maker, for example, was largely occupied with purely mechanical opera- 
 tions, most of them of a very elementary nature, such as a machine can do 
 quite as well as a man. Each of these operations required great concen- 
 tration of attention, leaving him very little opportunity for other forms of 
 mental activity. He was the slave of each particular task as truly as a 
 modern machine worker can be said to be the slave of his single task. 
 But the old-fashioned shoemaker had to turn from one kind of work to an- 
 other. This increased the difficulty, and, on the whole, required of him a 
 greater amount of concentration than is now required of the operator of a 
 machine. The latter, who has but one routine task to learn, learns it 
 easily, and can carry it out without very intense concentration of mind. 
 His mind, therefore, would seem to be freer than that of the old hand 
 worker, though there was more variety to the work of the latter. Whether 
 this greater variety is to his advantage or disadvantage would be difficult 
 to determine offhand. It looks as though the operator of a machine in a 
 shoe factory, being relieved of the necessity of acquiring several forms of 
 specialized manual dexterity, would be in a better position for free mental 
 activity than the old-fashioned shoemaker." l 
 
 It seems that those who declaim against factory life do not dis- 
 tinguish those things which are temporary and those things which 
 are inherent in the system. Long hours, insanitary conditions of 
 work, and frequent industrial accidents need not be inevitable ac- 
 companiments of the use of machinery. It is the efficiency of 
 machine methods that makes leisure possible for the workingmen, 
 and when they learn to use that leisure sanely, their condition will 
 
 *T. N. Carver, "Machinery and the Laborers," Quarterly Journal of Eco- 
 nomics, February, 1908, p. 230.
 
 PRODUCTION I3I 
 
 be far in advance of what it could be under more primitive methods 
 of production. 
 
 The charge is also brought against machine production that it 
 is antagonistic to the development of art. Machine production 
 means uniform production. It is possible that a growth in the 
 desire for what is beautiful rather than cheap will limit the use of 
 machinery in some directions (e.g. we may insist upon more hand 
 work in the making of furniture), but an extensive use of machinery 
 will always be necessary as a servant of art, and that in two ways: 
 (i) for an appreciation of art there must be leisure, or at least 
 leisurely work, and without machine methods this is not possible 
 for the masses; (2) there is much work that is preliminary to the 
 work of the artist, and that can be done by machinery. Will a 
 building be less artistic because much of the heavy work of dress- 
 ing the stone is done by machinery? 
 
 Territorial Division of Labor. The concentration of a certain 
 industry in a particular region is often called the territorial division 
 of labor, or the localization of industry. Illustrations are seen in 
 the prominence of the boot and shoe industry in Massachusetts; 
 the collar and cuff manufacture in Troy, New York ; oyster can- 
 ning in Baltimore; the manufacture of gloves in Gloversville and 
 Johnstown, New York ; of coke in the Connellsville district, 
 Pennsylvania; of brass ware in Waterbury, Connecticut; of carpets 
 in Philadelphia; of jewelry in Providence, Rhode Island. Attleboro, 
 and North Attleboro; slaughtering and meat packing in Chicago; 
 the manufacture of plated and britannia ware in Meriden, Con- 
 necticut; and the manufacture of silk in Paterson, New Jersey. 
 The following causes of localization have been mentioned: (i) prox- 
 imity to raw material, (2) accessibility to markets, (3) presence of 
 water power, (4) favorable climate, (5) availability of labor, 
 (6) availability of capital, and (7) the momentum of an early start. 
 The explanation of how these causes have operated in particular 
 instances is left as an exercise for the student. 1 
 
 1 Consult Hall, "The Localization of Industry," Census Bulletin, No. 244 (also 
 found in Twelfth Census, Manufactures), and Ross, "The Localization of 
 Industry," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. X, p. 247- Also the Federal 
 Census of Manufactures for 1905, Vol. I, Chap. XII.
 
 132 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Productive Organization of the American People. According 
 to the Census of 1900, nearly two fifths of the total population and 
 about one half of the population ten years of age and over are 
 engaged in gainful occupations. In the following table the extent 
 to which persons in each age group are gainfully employed is shown 
 for each sex : 
 
 TABLE I 
 
 NUMBER OF MALES AND OF FEMALES OF EACH SPECIFIED AGE ENGAGED 
 IN GAINFUL OCCUPATIONS COMPARED WITH THE TOTAL NUMBER OF 
 THE SAME SEX AND AGE : 
 
 AGE GROUPS 
 
 MALES 10 YEARS OF 
 AGE AND OVER. 
 PER CENT OF TOTAL 
 IN EACH GROUP 
 
 FEMALES 10 YEARS OF 
 AGE AND OVER. 
 PER CENT OF TOTAL 
 IN EACH GROUP 
 
 10 to 15 years 
 
 26 i 
 
 IO 2 
 
 1 6 to 20 years 
 
 768 
 
 12 1 
 
 21 to 24 years 
 
 m i 
 
 10 8 
 
 2C to id. vears . . 
 
 06 i 
 
 
 3S to 44. years . . 
 
 96 6 
 
 it 6 
 
 45 to 54 years 
 
 os e 
 
 14 7 
 
 ? <j to 64 vears . . 
 
 no o 
 
 
 65 years and over. 
 
 68 4 
 
 
 Age unknown 
 
 TO 6 
 
 2A 2 
 
 Aggregate .. . 
 
 80 o 
 
 18 8 
 
 
 
 
 The fact that women at work in their own households are not 
 counted as gainful workers is apparent from this table. The 
 effect of school attendance is seen in earlier age groups. In the 
 column for the female workers the effect of marriage is seen in the 
 decline in the percentages after twenty years. Old age makes its 
 influence felt in both columns. 
 
 The following table shows the distribution of the gainful workers 
 among the five main classes of occupations. The most striking 
 facts are the decline in the relative importance of agricultural pur- 
 suits and the increase in the relative importance of trade and 
 transportation : 
 
 ' Twelfth Census, Special Report on Occupations, 1904, p. cxviii.
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 DISTRIBUTION BY MAIN CLASSES OF PERSONS ENGAGED IN GAINFUL 
 OCCUPATIONS x 
 
 
 IQOO 
 
 1890 
 
 1880 
 
 Agricultural pursuits 
 
 If 7 
 
 
 
 Professional service 
 
 A. 1 
 
 A O 
 
 
 Domestic and personal service 
 
 IQ 2 
 
 18 t 
 
 IQ 6 
 
 Trade and transportation 
 
 16 4 
 
 IA 1 
 
 10 8 
 
 Manufacturing and mechanical pursuits. . 
 
 24.4 
 
 24.4 
 
 21.8 
 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 The broad territorial division of labor is seen when these per- 
 centages are given separately for groups of states : 
 
 TABLE III 
 
 PER CENT OF GAINFUL WORKERS IN EACH CLASS OF OCCUPATIONS BY 
 GROUPS OF STATES: 1900 2 
 
 
 AGRICULTURE 
 
 PROFESSIONAL 
 SERVICE 
 
 DOMESTIC AND 
 PERSONAL 
 
 TRADE AND 
 TRANSPOR- 
 TATION 
 
 FISHING 
 
 MINING AND 
 QUARRYING 
 
 MANUFACTURES 
 PROPER 
 
 North Atlantic 
 
 12. C 
 
 4.8 
 
 21.6 
 
 21.8 
 
 O.7 
 
 2.3 
 
 l6.7 
 
 South Atlantic 
 
 qo.8 
 
 3.0 
 
 20. o 
 
 IO.C 
 
 0.6 
 
 I.O 
 
 14.1 
 
 North Central . 
 
 ?6.6 
 
 <r.O 
 
 18.4 
 
 17.4 
 
 O.I 
 
 1.7 
 
 20.8 
 
 South Central 
 
 67.4. 
 
 2.Q 
 
 1C. 2 
 
 Q.I 
 
 O.I 
 
 I.O 
 
 8.3 
 
 Western 
 
 27. -z 
 
 c.7 
 
 21.8 
 
 IQ.4 
 
 o.s 
 
 7.4 
 
 17. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 In Table IV the various occupations differentiated in the Census 
 Report on Occupations have been classified somewhat in accord- 
 ance with their natural ranking, the amount of skill they require, 
 and the educational influence which they exercise over the people 
 who follow them. In each element of the population the females 
 
 1 Twelfth Census Special Report on Occupations, 1004, p. btxxvi. 
 * Special Report on Occupations, 1904, pp. xciv and cii.
 
 J 34 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 are found to a larger extent than the males in the lower grades of 
 skill. For both male and female negroes, the percentage of those 
 engaged in unskilled labor is very large. For the other elements 
 of the population there is an upward trend out of this lowest 
 
 grade. 
 
 
 
 TABLE IV 
 
 PERCENTAGE OF NATIVE AND FOREIGN BORN ELEMENTS AND NEGROES 
 ENGAGED IN THE SPECIAL GROUPS OF OCCUPATIONS CLASSIFIED BY 
 SEX : 1880, 1890, AND 1900 
 
 NATIVITY AND SEX 
 
 YEAE 
 
 PROPRIETARY 
 
 PROFESSIONAL 
 
 CLERICAL 
 
 SKILLED 
 LABOR 
 
 FACTORY 
 LABOR 
 
 UNSKILLED 
 LABOR 
 
 Native Born 
 Males 
 
 1880 
 
 3C QI 
 
 7.12 
 
 d.2Q 
 
 ii. si; 
 
 <;.8* 
 
 -to.-io 
 
 Native Born 
 Females 
 
 1890 
 1900 
 
 1880 
 
 35-82 
 
 3 I '4I 
 
 -1.28 
 
 3-74 
 3-9 6 
 
 7-<;4 
 
 6-75 
 9.00 
 
 1.61 
 
 J 4-59 
 
 15.20 
 
 1.62 
 
 6.26 
 6-43 
 
 20.65 
 
 32.84 
 34-oo 
 
 66.30 
 
 Foreign Born 
 Males 
 
 1890 
 1900 
 
 1880 
 
 7.72 
 8.67 
 
 27.81 
 
 9-32 
 12.50 
 
 2.O2 
 
 5-36 
 12.50 
 
 2.78 
 
 2.IO 
 
 2.8 3 
 
 I7-S8 
 
 23.40 
 29.00 
 
 I3-25 
 
 52.10 
 34-5 
 
 36.56 
 
 Foreign Born 
 Females 
 
 1890 
 1900 
 
 1880 
 
 24.77 
 23-3 6 
 
 4.l6 
 
 2-15 
 
 2-45 
 2.t;6 
 
 4.18 
 5-" 
 
 .82 
 
 19.98 
 19-45 
 
 1.58 
 
 12.78 
 14.19 
 
 ^o. 37 
 
 36.14 
 
 35-44 
 
 60. ?2 
 
 Negroes 
 Male 
 
 1890 
 1900 
 
 1890 
 
 7.08 
 7-95 
 
 26.65 
 
 2.52 
 2.94 
 
 i. 20 
 
 2-39 
 4.70 
 
 .3Q 
 
 1.82 
 I. 7 I 
 
 6. 07 
 
 27.46 
 30.18 
 
 2. -27 
 
 58.37 
 52.52 
 
 62.72 
 
 Negroes 
 Female 
 
 1900 
 1890 
 
 25.98 
 
 C.4.C 
 
 '*5 
 
 ,QO 
 
 .46 
 
 .08 
 
 5-5 1 
 
 3-92 
 
 2.QI 
 
 62.98 
 OO.o6 
 
 
 1900 
 
 6.07 
 
 1.19 
 
 .12 
 
 .04 
 
 2.86 
 
 89-72 
 
 Prepared by Mr. H. J. Dahl, of the University of Wisconsin, from the Reports of the 
 Twelfth Census, and from Mr. W. C. Hunt's monograph, entitled. Workers al Gainful Occu- 
 pations, published in the Bulletin of the Department of Labor, No. n, July, 1897.
 
 PRODUCTION 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 J 35 
 
 1. Is the employee in a planing mill in a worse position than the old-time 
 carpenter who has to do his planing by hand ? 
 
 2. Is an insurance agent a producer of wealth? 
 
 3. What would happen if there should be too much saving? 
 
 4. When you spend money, do you ordinarily think of how hard you had 
 to work to get it? 
 
 5. Why is Massachusetts the center of the boot and shoe industry ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. II. 
 
 FISHER, IRVING. The Nature of Capital and Income, Chaps. V and VI. 
 
 HOBSON, J. A. The Social Problem, Book II, Chap. II. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, Book IV. 
 
 VEBLEX, T. B. The Theory of Business Enterprise, Chaps. II and IIL 
 
 Valuable collateral reading will be found in recent bulletins of the 
 Census Bureau describing specific branches of production.
 
 CHAPTER X 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 THE dominance of " business" in our present social economy is 
 so familiar and commonplace a thing that we are apt to forget its 
 real significance. But it indicates, as nothing else does, the 
 cleavage that exists in modern times between money making and 
 the other things of life between exchange economy and domes- 
 tic economy. Commerce and manufactures have each in turn 
 been brought under the dominion of business enterprise; busi- 
 ness methods and motives are also of the first importance in 
 agriculture, although in this last field production for domestic 
 use still continues and promises to continue hand in hand with 
 production for the market. 
 
 "Business" means profit seeking. It does not cover so broad 
 a field as does "production," nor is it quite the same thing as 
 "production for the market." Business is acquisitive rather 
 than productive, and while acquisition usually implies produc- 
 tion, this is not invariably the case. The economic world, in its 
 business aspect, is a world of buying and selling rather than of 
 making and using things; it is a.world in which prices, expenses, 
 debts and credits, and contractual relations are the dominating 
 things rather than the technical processes of production or the 
 ultimate costs of production as measured in human effort and 
 sacrifice. 
 
 The Nature of Business Units. Under competitive conditions 
 profit seeking involves risk taking. The business world is made 
 up of profit-seeking, risk-taking units, entrepreneurial units. 
 We are apt to think of business units as concrete things, com- 
 posed of individual men or groups of men. In an ultimate 
 sense this is true, but for present purposes we may more profit- 
 
 136
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 137 
 
 ably view business units as abstract things, the centers or 
 foci of the contractual and other legal relations that bind the 
 business world together. These relations are recorded and stated 
 more or less fully in the accounts of each business unit; ulti- 
 mately, however, they are matters of legal fact, and, as we shall 
 see, the legal aspect and the accounting aspect of these relations 
 are not always identical. 
 
 Without entering into either the general theory or the details 
 of accounting, we may note that the simplest general way in 
 which a business unit can be described by its accounts is by 
 means of the income statement, which is a simple record of money 
 receipts and money expenditures during a given period, such as 
 a month or a year. Of more significance, however, in the present 
 connection, is the balance sheet, which is the statement of the 
 assets or resources and the liabilities or obligations of the busi- 
 ness unit as they exist at a particular time. The income state- 
 ment is a historical record, the balance sheet a photographic 
 snap-shot. 1 The following is a simplified form of balance sheet 
 for a small manufacturing establishment : 
 
 ASSETS 
 
 Land and buildings $190,000 
 
 Machinery and fixtures. . . 50,000 
 Raw materials, goods in 
 
 process, and finished 
 
 goods on hand 60,000 
 
 Accounts receivable 8,000 
 
 Cash on hand and in banks 7,000 
 
 Total assets $315,000 
 
 LIABILITIES 
 
 Original capital invested. $200,000 
 
 Income reinvested 60,000 
 
 Accounts payable 30,000 
 
 Profits 25,000 
 
 Total liabilities $315,000 
 
 The itemized assets explain themselves, but the meaning of 
 the various liabilities may not be so clear. In this statement all 
 the items of the liabilities except "accounts payable" refer to the 
 liabilities of the business unit, as an abstract entity, to the owner 
 
 1 The profit-and-loss statement is another important exhibit. It differs from 
 the income statement in that it is a showing of the amount of sales in a given period 
 compared with the expense of producing the particular things sold. Accurate 
 profit-and-loss statements represent the highest achievements of modern account- 
 ing and cost-keeping methods.
 
 138 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 or owners of the business, the amount which would be left if 
 the business were sold as a whole at a price just equal to the 
 total imputed value of the assets minus the actual outstanding 
 obligations (the accounts payable). 1 It will be noted that the 
 item called "profits" is the variable by which the account is 
 balanced. On such a showing as this the owners might decide 
 to take $5000 out of the business as dividends, or personal profits, 
 as the case may be. This would reduce the "cash " to $2000 and 
 correspondingly reduce profits. They may decide, also, per- 
 manently to retain $10,000 of their earnings in the business. 
 "Profits" would then be reduced to $10,000, and the "income 
 reinvested" or "surplus," as it is often called, would be increased 
 to $70,000. In practice "surplus" and "profits" often constitute 
 only one item in the accounts. In the case of corporations the 
 "original investment" item is called "capital" and represents 
 the par value of the corporation's securities, whether the full 
 amount has been actually paid in or not. Surplus profits in such 
 cases can be easily converted into "capital" by means of "stock 
 dividends." 
 
 In the legal aspect, however, the business does not always 
 appear to have so distinct a unity of its own. This varies with 
 the form of business organization, of which there are three im- 
 portant types: the individual entrepreneur, the partnership, and 
 the corporation. 
 
 The Individual Entrepreneur. Any individual may set him- 
 self up as a business man, an entrepreneur, without any legal 
 formality except the payment of the license fee which most states 
 impose on some kinds of business undertakings, such as liquor 
 dealing, and which some states, especially in the South, impose 
 upon many kinds of undertakings. The individual entrepreneur 
 still dominates the field in agriculture, small retail trade, and in 
 local "shop industries." 
 
 In the legal aspect the obligations of a business conducted by 
 
 1 The form of balance sheet given in the text is in reality a simple adaptation 
 of the kind of balance sheet used in the published statements of corporation 
 accounting. But if the individual proprietor of a small business keeps an accurate 
 ledger account with himself, the result is the same so far as the independence of 
 the business as an accounting unit is concerned.
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 139 
 
 an individual entrepreneur are the personal obligations of the 
 entrepreneur. All of his possessions of whatever kind * are 
 jeopardized by his business risks. If the entrepreneur conducts 
 two distinct business undertakings, the assets of one may be 
 seized, if necessary, to secure the liabilities of the other. The 
 personal liability of the individual entrepreneur is accordingly 
 said to be unlimited. The usefulness of this kind of business 
 organization is limited, obviously, to small undertakings, where 
 the capital and credit of the individual business man are adequate. 
 
 Partnerships. A "firm" or partnership represents a joint 
 undertaking by individual entrepreneurs. Partnerships are most 
 common in mercantile undertakings of moderate size, in small 
 manufacturing establishments, and in the professions. This join- 
 ing of interests makes larger undertakings possible, but relatively 
 increases the personal liability of the individual members of the 
 firm. For each member is personally liable for all of the obliga- 
 tions contracted by the firm, as well as those contracted in the 
 ordinary course of business by any other one member of the 
 firm. 2 The partners may have a contract binding among them- 
 selves as to their respective contributions (of money or time), 
 shares in profits, and liabilities. But a member released from 
 personal liability by an agreement of this kind is still liable for 
 all obligations incurred by the firm. The agreement only gives 
 a basis for instituting legal proceedings to recover the amount of 
 his personal losses from the other members of the firm. 
 
 Aside from (i) the excessive personal liability involved, the 
 partnership is open to objection from the business man's point 
 
 1 The "exemption laws" of some states constitute an exception which does 
 not affect the principle involved. 
 
 2 This refers to the status of the ordinary partnership under common law. 
 The statutes of some states provide for a special form of limited partnership, in 
 which one or more of the partners are special partners, who are not personally 
 liable, save for their investment in the business, and who are allowed to take no 
 active part in the management of the business. In a few states there is a special 
 form called a limited partnership association, in which the liability of all the 
 partners is limited. These are practically joint-stock companies with non- 
 transferable shares. The partnership in commcndam, which still exists in Louisi- 
 ana as a heritage of the civil law, is essentially like the statutory limited partnerships 
 of other states.
 
 140 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of view, because : (2) It is impossible for a partner to retire from 
 a firm without dissolving the partnership and, possibly, break- 
 ing up the business. The death or insolvency of any partner has 
 the same effect. (3) A new member cannot enter the firm nor 
 can a member transfer his interests to another person without 
 the consent of all the members of a firm, requirements which 
 naturally follow from the nature of a partnership. (4) The 
 partnership form of organization is not adapted to undertakings 
 requiring large investments of capital and hence requiring the 
 cooperation of a large number of persons. What advantages the 
 partnership has come from the ease with which it can be organ- 
 ized and dissolved, and from its elasticity, that is, the ease 
 with which the contractual relations among the partners, bind- 
 ing as among themselves, can be altered to suit any contingencies 
 that may arise. 
 
 The Corporation. The federal census of 1905 showed that 
 although less than one fourth of the manufacturing undertakings 
 included in that enumeration were organized as corporations, 
 yet these produced nearly three fourths of the total manufactur- 
 ing product (measured in money value). Most banks and insur- 
 ance companies are corporations, while in the field of railway 
 transportation corporations are in almost exclusive control. Ac- 
 count should also be taken of the large and growing number of 
 mercantile undertakings organized as corporations. 
 
 In the case of the corporation the legal view and the account- 
 ing view of the business unit are practically identical. While 
 the ordinary partnership is in law simply a group of individual 
 entrepreneurs, the corporation is regarded, for some purposes, as 
 a "person." To the incorporated business unit, an abstract 
 thing, as we have seen, the law imputes some of the attributes 
 of personality, and of a personality distinct from that of the 
 individual men who are the stockholders of the corporation. 1 
 
 Municipalities, universities, monasteries, guilds, etc., were commonly 
 incorporated by royal charter long before business corporations of the 
 
 "Several states authorize the organization of "joint-stock companies" which 
 are like corporations in all essential particulars, and are sometimes called "quasi- 
 corporations." In theory they are incorporated partnerships with transferable 
 shares and (usually) with limited liability.
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 141 
 
 modern kind arose, for this did not occur until the rise of "capitalism" 
 in the seventeenth century. The great trading and colonizing companies, 
 such as the British East India Company, the Virginia Company, the Guinea 
 Company, etc., were the prototypes of the modern business corporation. 
 In.connection with these trading companies the joint-stock principle, which 
 had already been used in a few isolated instances of banking, was developed. 
 This was the practice of issuing certificates to those who made contributions 
 to the "joint stock" (or capital) of a company, which entitled the holder 
 to a proportionate share in the profits accruing to the joint stock. The 
 modern business corporation, like these early trading companies, is based 
 essentially on the combination of the joint-stock principle with the legal 
 recognition of the business unit as a distinct entity. 
 
 At the beginning of the nineteenth century what few corporations there 
 were in America were, for the most part, banks, insurance companies, or 
 canal and turnpike companies. The introduction of railways in the third 
 decade of the century greatly stimulated the organization of corporations, 
 because these new undertakings required larger investments of capital than 
 could be furnished by any individual or firm. State enterprise, it is true, 
 promised at one time to be an important factor in canal and railway building, 
 but such state undertakings were usually planned with the purpose of de- 
 veloping natural resources, attracting immigration, and building up the 
 .trade of particular districts and particular cities rather than of getting money 
 profits. Most of these state undertakings had succumbed by 1840, so that 
 the field was left open for business enterprise. In the general expansion and 
 reorganization of business that followed the Civil War the corporation form 
 of organization began to be more generally used for all kinds of business 
 undertakings. The growing importance of corporations in business life is 
 partly an effect and partly a cause of the growing size of the business unit. 
 
 The Corporation Charter. The corporation is a creature of 
 the state, its right to exist being dependent on a charter or on 
 articles of incorporation, granted or approved by the state. In- 
 corporation formerly necessitated a special act of the legislature 
 in each case. This gave opportunity for favoritism and monop- 
 oly and subjected corporations of all kinds to hostility and 
 suspicion. Most corporations are now organized under general 
 laws, whereby any group of men can secure a corporation charter 
 by complying with certain prescribed conditions. In fact, all 
 but six states now have constitutional provisions against the 
 granting of charters to business corporations by special act. 
 
 It was formerly a common practice to grant corporation char- 
 ters in perpetuity, but the decision of Chief Justice Marshall in
 
 142 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the Dartmouth College case, whereby the corporation charter 
 was declared to constitute a binding contract between the state 
 and the corporation, which could not be altered or amended by 
 the state except with the consent of the corporation, has led to 
 the general practice of limiting the life of corporations to terms 
 of from twenty to one hundred years, fifty years being a common 
 period. The corporation may, of course, secure a new charter 
 at the expiration of the old, but the limited term gives the state 
 the opportunity to change the requirements of the charter from 
 time to time, or to refuse reincorporation altogether, as may seem 
 most desirable. Most states, moreover, now specifically reserve 
 the right to alter or amend the corporation charter at pleasure. 
 
 Corporation charters, or articles of incorporation, usually con- 
 tain details relating to such matters as the purpose or purposes 
 for which the corporation is formed, its principal place of busi- 
 ness, the number of its directors, and the amount of its capitali- 
 zation. 
 
 Lack of Uniformity in State Laws. Many difficulties in the 
 public control of corporations have arisen from the fact that 
 while charters are granted by individual states, the activities of 
 many business corporations extend over the boundaries of many 
 states. Moreover, some states are much more lenient than 
 others in such matters as the control of capitalization, require- 
 ments as to publicity, limitations on the scope of activity of a 
 single corporation, taxes and fees, etc. New Jersey has become 
 known as the "home of corporations" despite the fact that some 
 states have even more lenient laws than New Jersey. New Jersey 
 has been favored, however, on account of the proximity of New 
 York City, the real home of most of the greater corporate in- 
 terests of the country, as well as on account of its early start 
 and the adaptability of its laws to the most modern type of cor- 
 poration, the holding company. (See p. 150.) 
 
 Other states, with stricter laws, could not prevent corporations 
 organized under lax laws from doing business within their terri- 
 tory so far as that business is interstate. So far, however, as a 
 corporation organized under the laws of one state carries on any 
 part of its business wholly within the borders of another state,
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 143 
 
 the latter state has the right of refusing to recognize it as a cor- 
 poration; that is, the right to treat it as a mere partnership. In 
 practice, however, one state freely recognizes the corporations of 
 another state under the rule of "interstate comity." In fact, 
 many corporations transact all their business outside the borders 
 of the state which chartered them. The real standards, therefore, 
 are the laxest standards, not the highest. More use on the part 
 of American states of the power of exacting certain standards 
 from "foreign corporations," as they are called, is much to be 
 desired. 
 
 Corporation Capital and Securities. In a strictly legal sense 
 the capitalization of a corporation is the amount of its authorized 
 capital stock. This capitalization represents, in theory, the 
 amount of money actually invested in the business by the original 
 stockholders. As a matter of fact, the full amount of the au- 
 thorized capital is rarely paid in at the organization of a new cor- 
 poration. The capitalization is apt to be, in practice, a purely 
 arbitrary thing, a nominal money sum divided into units or 
 shares, the relative holdings of different individuals being meas- 
 ured by the number of shares they own. 
 
 Corporation stock is divided into two general classes, pre- 
 ferred stock and common slock, although many corporations issue 
 only the latter. Preferred stock represents a prior claim on the 
 earnings of the corporation. A corporation which has "6 per 
 cent preferred stock" outstanding can pay no dividends to its 
 common stockholders until it has paid 6 per cent dividends on 
 its preferred stock. Preferred stock may be cumulative (in which 
 the prior claims to dividends accumulate from year to year, if 
 unpaid) or non-cumulative. It may or may not have any claim 
 on any part of the surplus profits remaining after a certain rate 
 of dividend has been paid on the common stock. There may be 
 several different grades of preferred stock, first preferred, 
 second preferred, etc. 
 
 In the popular use of the word the capitalization of a corpora- 
 tion includes also its funded debt. The funded debt is represented 
 by bonds, which are interest-bearing promises to pay certain sums 
 of money at definite times in the future. There are many differ-
 
 144 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ent kinds of bonds, but three principal classes are: (i) mortgage 
 bonds, (2) collateral trust bonds, (3) income and debenture 
 bonds. The first class is based on a mortgage of all or of a specific 
 part of the property of a corporation. Collateral trust bonds are 
 secured by the pledge of securities issued by other corporations, 
 but owned by the corporation issuing the bonds. They have 
 been much used in financing railway consolidations. Income 
 and debenture bonds are usually secured only by the earning 
 capacity of the business. Industrial corporations make less use 
 of bonds than do railways, and confine themselves usually to the 
 mortgage bond type, of which, however, there are many sub- 
 ordinate varieties. In the case of many corporations the mort- 
 gage security behind an issue of bonds is in itself not of great 
 importance, for the property mortgaged is apt to be worthless 
 except as an integral part of a unified business establishment. 
 The mere power of foreclosure, however, gives mortgage bond- 
 holders a position of strength in the reorganization of insolvent 
 corporations. 
 
 Bonds are sometimes said to represent "creditor interests," 
 and stock "entrepreneur interests." This statement is sugges- 
 tive and is fairly accurate. In fact, however, stock and bonds 
 are simply different kinds of equities in a business, conveying 
 the right to receive income, to share in the distribution of the 
 assets in case of insolvency, and to have a voice in the manage- 
 ment. Stockholders alone participate in the management of the 
 corporation, although bondholders are often able to dictate 
 policies when the affairs of a corporation are in a precarious con- 
 dition. Bonds differ from stock in being terminable at a definite 
 period of time in the future. In practice, however, the bonds of 
 great corporations are usually replaced by new issues as rapidly 
 as they mature. 
 
 Overcapitalization. Much has been said about the over- 
 capitalization of corporations, "stock-watering," as it is called. 
 Only a few states require that all the nominal capitalization 
 should represent capital actually invested. In most states, more- 
 over, it is not difficult for a corporation to increase its capitali- 
 zation from time to time in order to secure funds from the sale
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 '45 
 
 of securities, or (in the case of stock-dividends) in order to afford 
 a basis for the distribution of surplus profits without employing 
 an excessively high interest rate. It is this last cause of in- 
 creased capitalization that is of special importance in this con- 
 nection. 
 
 On the one hand it is urged that capitalization is a nominal 
 thing, that it is immaterial whether a corporation pays 12 per 
 cent dividends on $1,000,000 of capital stock or 6 per cent 
 dividends on $2,000,000 of capital stock. On the other hand it 
 is said that capitalization should not be a merely nominal thing, 
 but that it should represent the actual amount of the investment; 
 that, without regard to the amount of capitalization, regularly 
 recurring dividends of 12 per cent suggest excessive profits in a 
 way that 6 per cent dividends do not. 
 
 The argument in favor of a closer correspondence between 
 capitalization and real investment is especially strong in the 
 case of railways and other transportation corporations with 
 quasi-public functions, municipal public service corporations, 
 and corporations enjoying natural monopolies of all kinds. For 
 there is a growing feeling that such corporations are in a peculiar 
 sense social trustees, to whom have been committed certain 
 public economic functions that might very properly be per- 
 formed by the state, if that course were deemed the more advan- 
 tageous. That such corporations should be restricted to the 
 payment of a reasonable dividend on reasonable capitalization 
 would seem to be a proposition that is scarcely open to question. 1 
 Yet excessive profits are what make excessive dividends possible, 
 and whether profits are excessive or not can be determined in 
 most cases without reference to capitalization by the compulsory 
 use of adequate accounting methods. 
 
 Overcapitalization should be looked at also from the point of 
 view of the investor, a point of view too often overlooked. 
 When overcapitalization is permitted, it is frequently extremely 
 difficult and often, indeed, impossible for the ordinary investor 
 to know precisely what he is buying when he purchases a share 
 
 1 It is better to curtail excessive profits by public control of rates, prices, and 
 services than by arbitrarily limiting the dividend rate. 
 
 L
 
 146 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of stock of an overcapitalized company. It helps to approxi- 
 mate equality of opportunity for all when there is an exact cor- 
 respondence between investment and capitalization. If a person 
 buys a share of national bank stock at $4000, he at once knows 
 that the original investment was $100. The apparently high 
 price immediately challenges attention, and the investor is led to 
 look into the grounds of the high price. There are cases in which 
 such a price would prove a remunerative investment, but it is 
 well to warn the investing public by prohibition of overcapitali- 
 zation. It has been strongly urged, and with some ground, that 
 it is in every way highly desirable that the corporate property of 
 the country should be more widely distributed ; and to promote 
 this end, every measure which gives the average man a "square 
 deal" in investments must be strongly favored. 
 
 While overcapitalization has thus many undesirable features, 
 it has nevertheless sometimes been unduly emphasized in discus- 
 sions of corporation reform, to the neglect of other and more 
 important points. 
 
 In this connection we should note the difference between the 
 "capitalization" and the "capital" of a corporation. The busi- 
 ness world uses the term "capital" in two ways: it speaks of the 
 total permanent investments, the amount of money "tied up," 
 in a business as its capital, and it also speaks of the total sell- 
 ing value of the business as a whole as its capital. This last may 
 depend in part on such intangible things as monopoly power or 
 good will. It is measured by the "capitalized" earning capacity 
 of the business, or, approximately, by the market value of the 
 corporation's securities, as distinct from the par values which 
 measure the nominal capitalization of the corporation. 
 
 Form of Capitalization. A significant feature of recent de- 
 velopment in corporation finance is the multiplicity of types of 
 corporate securities. It is no uncommon thing, for example, for 
 the equities in a railway corporation (in addition to the floating 
 debt, or accounts payable) to be divided among a dozen or twenty 
 varieties of bonds and two or three varieties of stock. This 
 multiplicity of securities is of advantage to the corporation in 
 that it enables it to offer to investors and speculators a carefully
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 147 
 
 graded assortment of risks, a fact which makes the total sell- 
 ing value of a corporation's securities greater than it would other- 
 wise be. This complex kind of capitalization has, however, some 
 undesirable features. If the owners of a particular security, 
 the common stockholders, perhaps, control the corporation, 
 they may desire to increase the value of their securities for specu- 
 lative purposes by the payment of unearned dividends, very 
 properly a criminal proceeding according to the laws of some states 
 a proceeding which would be opposed to the interests of the hold- 
 ers of all the other securities of the corporation. Moreover, in 
 cases of insolvency and reorganization, it is a difficult matter to 
 untangle and to adjust equitably the rights of the holders of the 
 different kinds of securities. 
 
 In times of prosperity corporations often pay for extensions of 
 their plants from the proceeds of bond sales, because it is esti- 
 mated that the earning power of such extensions will more than 
 suffice to pay the interest on the bonds and will afford a hand- 
 some surplus for the stockholders. Corporations thus accumu- 
 late in prosperous times an unwieldy load of fixed charges in the 
 form of interest on bonds, a fact which is apt to be a source 
 of difficulty in less prosperous years. In periods of financial 
 stringency these fixed charges are a common cause of insolvency, 
 receiverships, and consequent reorganizations, from which the 
 bondholders are apt to emerge as stockholders, and in which 
 the stockholders are apt to lose their holdings. The legal restric- 
 tion of the securities issued by any one corporation to one kind 
 of stock and three or four varieties of bonds is both feasible and 
 desirable. Nor should the bonded debt be allowed to greatly 
 exceed the amount of the paid-up capital stock. 
 
 Corporation Management. The management of business cor- 
 porations is, as a rule, in the hands of boards of directors, elected 
 by the stockholders from among their own number. The details 
 of management are in the hands of officers, chosen usually by the 
 directors. In principle this system achieves something like repre- 
 sentative government of the affairs of the corporation. In prac- 
 tice, in the larger corporations, some of the directors are apt to 
 be "dummy directors," usually employees of the corporation,
 
 148 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 made directors in order to complete the number prescribed in 
 the charter, or are the representatives of great financial in- 
 terests, and often of competing interests. Directors of this latter 
 sort are not primarily concerned with the management of a cor- 
 poration in the interests of its stockholders and bondholders. 
 They are directors for the purpose of guarding special interests, 
 and in many cases for the purpose of preventing "competition" 
 from becoming anything more active than an armed peace. 
 
 In many cases the real direction of a corporation's policies is 
 in the hands of an "executive committee " or "finance committee " 
 of three or five directors representing the person or persons in 
 actual control of the corporation. 
 
 Advantages of the Corporation as a Form of Business Organ- 
 ization. From the point of view of the business man the cor- 
 poration presents decided advantages over the partnership for 
 all undertakings of considerable size. Some of its points of 
 superiority are: (i) Stockholders usually have no personal lia- 
 bility for the corporation's obligations except so far as the full 
 par value of their stockholdings has not been paid up. 1 (2) The 
 relative permanence and stability of the corporation are of decided 
 advantage, especially in undertakings requiring large invest- 
 ments of capital in relatively fixed and permanent forms. (3) The 
 concentration of executive power in the hands of directors and 
 officers leads to efficiency in management. (4) The transfer- 
 ability of corporation securities makes it possible for stockholders 
 to enter or leave the undertaking at pleasure. (5) The division 
 of the securities into small units and into different grades and 
 classes affords opportunities to all kinds of investors, the small 
 and the large, the conservative and the venturesome. (6) All of 
 the advantages named make it easier for the corporation to 
 attract and to use efficiently large amounts of capital, furnished 
 by many different investors. 
 
 Social Aspects of the Growth of Corporations. That corpora- 
 tions do possess desirable features, from the point of view of 
 
 1 Exception should be made of banking and insurance corporations, in the case 
 of which "double liability" on the part of the stockholders is common. A few 
 states impose some measure of personal liability upon the stockholders of all 
 corporations organized under their laws.
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 149 
 
 business interests, is a fact clearly evidenced by the unprecedented 
 growth of this form of business organization. In the main, effi- 
 ciency for business purposes, for money making, means efficiency 
 from the social point of view, productive efficiency, also. But, 
 nevertheless, the two viewpoints are not identical, and what is 
 desirable from one point of view is not always desirable from 
 the other point of view. 
 
 The gap between money making and service to society (never 
 quite identical things) is distinctly widened when those in control 
 of a corporation's policies subordinate the profits to be obtained 
 by the sale of its products to the profits to be obtained by specu- 
 lation in its securities. Many of our greatest corporations are 
 directed by men to whom fluctuations in capital values (as repre- 
 sented in the prices of securities) are a much more important 
 source of personal income than are the net earnings of such 
 corporations. The payment^ of unearned dividends, the non- 
 payment of earned dividends, the direction of a corporation's 
 policy for the benefit of the holders of one kind of security among 
 the different ones issued by the corporation, the effecting of cor- 
 porate combinations and reorganizations that will affect the stock 
 exchange rather than the produce market, these are some of 
 the more obvious results of the unfortunate relation between 
 corporation management and speculation in corporation securi- 
 ties. 
 
 It should also be noted in this connection that the growth of 
 corporations is bringing with it a subtle but very significant 
 change in the nature of the institution of private property. So 
 far as a large and increasing proportion of productive wealth is 
 concerned, we are losing that direct relation of ownership be- 
 tween men and goods which Arthur Young had in mind when he 
 said, "The magic of property turns sand into gold." We often 
 have, instead, several layers of corporation securities interposed 
 between the ultimate owners and the ultimate objects of owner- 
 ship. The effect of this will undoubtedly be to bring about the 
 more thorough domination of business principles in the business 
 world. Sentiment, the honored traditions of long-established 
 firms, the "pride of ownership," the joy of workmanship (which
 
 150 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 may be felt by the employer who turns out a good product, as 
 well as by the workman) are bound to yield yet more completely 
 to the sway of the cold logic of corporation accounts and stock- 
 market quotations. The adequacy of purely business principles 
 as the foundation of our economic life will be tested more thoroughly 
 under the corporation form of organization than ever before. 
 
 Trusts. A distinctive feature of the economic development 
 of the past thirty years has been the combination of individual 
 corporations into larger concerns, or trusts. The "trust," in the 
 technical sense, involved either giving a board of trustees the 
 absolute control of the actual properties of the different con- 
 cerns in the combination, or what amounted to the same thing, 
 assigning the stock of each corporation, with its voting power, 
 to them in exchange for "trust certificates," on which dividends 
 were paid. The Standard Oil Trust of 1882 was the first com- 
 bination of this kind, but it was speedily followed by several 
 others. In 1890, in a case brought by the state of New York 
 against the sugar trust, the trust agreement was held to be illegal 
 under common law. Corporate combinations were not destroyed 
 by this decision. They changed, however, to a more definitely 
 coherent form, that in which a single great corporation domi- 
 nates the consolidation. 
 
 In most cases, this corporation, which is usually organized 
 for the purpose, does not own the actual plants of the various 
 concerns in the combination, but simply owns all or a majority of 
 the stock of each. It is accordingly called a " holding company." 
 The holding company exchanges its own securities for the securi- 
 ties of constituent companies, or, when necessary, it buys the 
 securities of the constituent companies with funds secured from 
 the sale of its own securities, sometimes by the sale of bonds 
 secured by the pledge of the securities of constituent companies 
 as collateral. Not only in industrial consolidations, 1 but also in 
 railway and electric railroad mergers has the holding company 
 device become important. 
 
 1 A very complete list of "trusts," prepared by Mr. Byron W. Holt for the 
 World Alumnae (1908), contains the names of about 250 industrial combinations, 
 most of which are holding companies.
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 15! 
 
 From the point of view of business organization the holding 
 company is simply an extension of the principle of the corpora- 
 tion. The holding company needs for purposes of control only 
 a majority interest in the stocks of its subsidiary corporations. 
 Various holding companies may in turn be combined by means 
 of one larger holding company, and the process may, and 
 does, go even further. An individual capitalist may, by an 
 investment of $1,000,000, for example, control a holding company 
 with a stock issue of $2,000,000, which in turn may control cor- 
 porations with $4,000,000 of stock outstanding, 1 and some of 
 these last may in their turn be holding companies. The result 
 is a tremendous concentration of industrial and financial power, 
 with the minimum of liability. The uncontrolled use of the 
 holding company device leads to neglect of the interests of the 
 minority stockholders in the various corporations concerned; to 
 difficulty in fixing the legal responsibility for corporate mis- 
 deeds; to an undesirable complexity in the economic and legal 
 relations of the holders of securities in the different corporations, 
 and to the subordination of industrial to speculative ends. 
 
 The "trust problem," however, has attracted more attention 
 as a problem of monopoly than as a problem of business organi- 
 zation. The problem of monopoly will be considered in another 
 chapter. Here it is sufficient to note that combination and 
 monopoly are not identical things, that we may have either one 
 without the other. It is true, however, that the movement toward 
 combination originated as one manifestation of the efforts of men 
 engaged in competitive undertakings to escape from the restraints 
 imposed upon them by the fact of competition. Price agreements, 
 selling bureaus, division of territory, limitation of output, pool- 
 ing, etc., are other forms of the same general effort. 
 
 The specific motives usually mentioned as the most important 
 causes of corporate combinations are (i) the greater economy of 
 the large-scale business; (2) the elimination of purely competi- 
 tive expenses (some kinds of advertising, for example) ; (3) the 
 
 1 It is assumed, for convenience, that the stock in each case is worth par and 
 that the ownership of half of it will give substantial control. In the case of in- 
 dustrial combinations ownership of all the stock of the subsidiary companies by 
 the holding company is not uncommon.
 
 152 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 power to limit output and control price. The first of these fac- 
 tors suggests the difficult question of the most profitable size of 
 the business unit. Without discussing this point in detail in this 
 connection we may note that the significant thing is the most 
 economical size of the industrial plant rather than of the busi- 
 ness unit itself. Some of our present-day business units are so 
 large that they operate a number of duplicate plants. To that 
 extent, at least, they are larger than is necessary to secure maxi- 
 mum technical efficiency. Whether competitive expenses and 
 competitive prices are eliminated by combination depends on 
 whether the combination has any real basis of monopoly power 
 over and above the mere fact of combination, which, taken alone, 
 can give at most only a temporary monopoly. 
 
 It is plain, however, that if any or all of these three classes of 
 advantages do exist in the case of a particular combination, the 
 earning power of the combination will be greater than the total 
 earning power of the separate concerns before consolidation, 
 a difference which will be reflected in the value of the securities 
 of the holding company. It is this increment in capital value, 
 due to the real or expected advantages of consolidation, that has 
 been the chief cause of such combinations. The organization of 
 trusts has in many cases been effected by professional "pro- 
 moters," whose connection with an undertaking does not con- 
 tinue any longer than is necessary in order to secure the profits 
 of consolidation. A few great trusts like those which dominate 
 in the oil, sugar, steel, and tobacco industries have been con- 
 spicuously successful in a business way. Many others were 
 "made to sell "; that is, were organized only in order that profits 
 might be gained through the sale of their securities, and have 
 been weighted down by a capitalization not justified by their 
 actual earning capacity. Some of these have already been re- 
 organized, with diminished capitalization; others, possibly, only 
 await the test of a prolonged period of financial depression. 
 
 Anti-trust Laws. Most states have statutes and some have 
 constitutional provisions against "combinations in restraint of 
 trade." These are aimed primarily against the large corpora- 
 tions of the kind described, although if strictly construed they
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 '53 
 
 also make illegal the whole mass of price agreements and trade 
 restrictions, general and local, which are a much more common 
 and characteristic feature of modern business than is generally 
 supposed. Anti-trust statutes have accomplished but little, be- 
 cause they have been aimed at forms rather than at facts, at 
 symptoms rather than at fundamental causes. If there is mo- 
 nopoly, with resulting high and discriminatory prices, the social 
 action needed is the rooting out of the fundamental cause of 
 monopoly, or, in some cases, a frank recognition of the fact of 
 monopoly, coupled with the proper public regulation of prices 
 and services. If evils appear in the undue concentration of 
 financial power, and in the dominance of speculative motives in 
 business management, the social action needed is more stringent 
 control of the methods, purposes, and conditions of corporation 
 organization and corporation management. The corporation 
 problem and the monopoly problem are distinct things. The 
 "trust problem" may mean either one thing or the other. 
 
 The Sherman anti-trust act of 1890 is a federal law, making 
 "combinations in restraint of trade" criminal, so far as the 
 field of interstate commerce is concerned. It has the defects of 
 the similar enactments of the individual states. It has been 
 used to some extent by the government as a means of breaking 
 up railway combinations, but the results of this application of 
 the Sherman act have been generally considered to be unfortunate. 
 
 Publicity. There is a general agreement among students of 
 corporation problems that greater publicity as to the details of 
 corporate management is much to be desired, both as an end 
 in itself, and as constituting a basis for the intelligent control 
 of corporations. We may distinguish four kinds of publicity: 
 (i) opening of accounts and records to the inspection of stock- 
 holders; (2) opening of accounts and records to the proper admin- 
 istrative officials of the state or federal governments; (3) periodi- 
 cal financial statements to stockholders; (4) periodical financial 
 statements to proper administrative officials. 
 
 Of these different kinds of publicity the second, third, and 
 fourth are unquestionably desirable. The publicity of railway 
 accounts and the development of uniform railroad accounting
 
 154 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 under the interstate commerce law has been of great benefit to 
 the public, to investors, and to the railways themselves. In re- 
 spect to the first kind of publicity mentioned, it can hardly be 
 thought right that every small stockholder should have an un- 
 limited right of access to a corporation's books, especially in 
 competitive undertakings. 
 
 Federal Control of Corporations. It has been suggested by 
 many writers that the unfortunate effects of the lack of uniform 
 state requirements as to publicity, capitalization, purposes of 
 corporation organization, etc., could be remedied to some extent 
 by federal action. Canal, railway, and bridge companies have 
 in the past been chartered by the federal government, just as 
 national banks are now. It would be legally possible and eco- 
 nomically advisable to require at least a federal license from all 
 corporations engaging in interstate commerce. Moderate and just 
 requirements as to publicity, and possibly as to capitalization 
 and other things, might very well be imposed as the price of a 
 federal license. Aside from the present lack of uniformity in 
 state laws, the mere size of modern business corporations and the 
 extent of their operations make it difficult for any individual 
 state or states to control them efficiently. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. What are the terms under which corporations are chartered in your 
 own state? What "anti -trust" laws are in force there? 
 
 2. Explain the various items in the published balance sheet of some in- 
 dustrial corporation. 
 
 3. What limitations should be attached to the statement that "a corpora- 
 tion is a fictitious person." 
 
 4. Does the word "capital" mean the same thing in accounting and in 
 economics ? 
 
 5. Report on the history of one of the following: United States Steel 
 Corporation; American Sugar Refining Company; American Tobacco 
 Company; International Harvester Company.
 
 BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 155 
 
 BENTLEY, H. C. Corporate Finance and Accounting. 
 
 Commissioner of Corporations, Annual and Special Reports. 
 
 CONYNGTON, THOMAS. Corporate Management ; and Corporate Organization. 
 
 FREUND, ERNST. The Legal Nature of Corporations. 
 
 GREENE, T. L. Corporation Finance. 
 
 HALLE, E. L. VON. Trusts, or Industrial Combinations and Coalitions in 
 
 the United States. 
 
 HORACK, F. E. The Organization and Control of Industrial Corporations. 
 Industrial Commission, Report, Vols. I, II, XIII, XVIII, XIX. (See 
 
 general index in Vol. XIX under "Combinations," "Corporations," 
 
 "Capitalization," etc.) 
 JENKS, J. W. The Trust Problem. 
 MEADE, E. S. Trust Finance. 
 MONTAGUE, G. H. Trusts of To-day. 
 MOODY, JOHN. The Truth about the Trusts. 
 RIPLEY, W. Z. (ed.). Trusts, Pools, and Corporations. 
 SPARLING, S. E. Business Organization. 
 WILGUS, H. L. Should there be a Federal Incorporation Law for Commercial 
 
 Corporations ? 
 WOOD, W. A. Modern Business Corporations.
 
 PART IV 
 VALUE AND EXCHANGE 
 
 CHAPTER XI 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 IF every family produced all the goods needed to supply the 
 wants of its members, most of the problems which to-day confront 
 economic science would not exist. Most of the world's workers 
 are, however, contributing their services either directly or indirectly 
 (through the production of goods) toward the satisfaction of the 
 wants of others. One's economic well-being to-day depends pri- 
 marily on two things: the money income which can be got from 
 others in return for one's services or for the use of one's land or 
 capital, and the amount of things that can be bought with this 
 money income. The federal census of 1900 showed that about 
 93 per cent of the men over twenty years old and about 1 8 per cent 
 of the women of corresponding age were employed in money-mak- 
 ing occupations; and this number does not include those land- 
 lords and capitalists whose income was derived entirely from 
 their investments. The work of the housewife and the services of 
 friendship embody utilities, that is, satisfy human wants, just as 
 do money-making activities, but they are not measured in terms 
 of dollars and cents. The production of wealth is in these days 
 mostly "for the market," and wants are satisfied very largely by 
 goods obtained from the market. Most goods get from those who 
 produce them to those who use them only by the processes of 
 exchange. 
 
 The Meaning and Significance of Value. One of the most 
 fundamental of all economic problems relates to the ratios at 
 which goods are exchanged for one another. These ratios are 
 
 156
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 157 
 
 called exchange values. The exchange value of a good is the quan- 
 tity of other goods that can be obtained for it. Exchange value is 
 often called objective value, and is to be sharply distinguished 
 from subjective value, which, it will be remembered, measures 
 the importance attached by an individual to a particular unit of a 
 commodity. In this chapter the word " value " is to be understood 
 as meaning exchange value. It is evident that the value of a 
 commodity will vary with conditions of time and place, and that 
 at any particular time and place it might be expressed in a num- 
 ber of different ways. A pair of shoes might be exchanged for 
 four bushels of wheat, for two hats, or for other quantities of other 
 commodities. In this sense any one commodity will have not one, 
 but many, exchange values. It is, however, customary to-day to 
 express the values of all commodities in terms of one other com- 
 modity, money. Price is exchange value expressed in terms of 
 money. There are 23.22 grains of gold in our monetary unit, the 
 gold dollar. Thus, when we say that a pair of shoes is worth four 
 dollars, we indicate that they have four times the value of 23.22 
 grains of gold. When the words " value " and " price " are used in- 
 terchangeably, as will sometimes be the case in this chapter, there 
 is implied the assumption that the value of money is constant an 
 assumption which, of course, does not entirely correspond with 
 the facts. 
 
 The process by which the ratios at which goods are exchanged 
 is determined is called " valuation." This word is used in a narrow 
 sense as referring to the fixing of the exchange values of commodi- 
 ties; in a broader sense it includes also the determination of the 
 different rewards received by those who have contributed to the 
 production of these commodities. In this broad sense the prob- 
 lem of valuation is the problem of the distribution of wealth. Im- 
 agine the case of a mechanic employed at a particular time in 
 the manufacture of machinery that will be used in a flour mill. 
 The final product of the mechanic's labor the only product 
 directly useful in the satisfaction of human wants is the flour, 
 or bread made from the flour. To the making of this final prod- 
 uct thousands besides our mechanic farmers, agricultural la- 
 borers, railway officers and employees, other mechanics, and so
 
 158 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 on in a practically endless list have contributed. What deter- 
 mines the value of the final product? What proportion of this 
 value goes to the mechanic? What is his share worth to him as 
 the means of getting the necessaries of life ? Of these three ques- 
 tions, the first and third fall within the problem of the valuation 
 of commodities; the second, relating to the valuation of the me- 
 chanic's services, falls within the problem of the distribution of 
 wealth. At present we are concerned with valuation in its nar- 
 rower sense, although the principles to be developed apply also 
 in the case of the valuation of the services of the factors in pro- 
 duction. The significance of the subject of value in economic 
 science lies in the fact that, within the conditions set by existing 
 institutions, and within the limits set by the total production of 
 wealth, human welfare, so far as it is dependent upon the pos- 
 session of economic goods, is largely determined by the process of 
 valuation. 
 
 The Market. It is conceivable that the values of goods might 
 be fixed by public authority, or that the production of the most 
 important commodities might be monopolized. Then, too, it is 
 possible to imagine a condition of society in which custom should 
 have such power that values, when once established, would be 
 changed very infrequently. Still another possibility would be a 
 regime of competition in which every man would be left free to 
 buy and sell as he pleased at such prices as he could get. The 
 first three factors public authority, monopoly, and custom 
 are among the things which determine the ratios at which goods 
 are actually exchanged to-day; but the dominant factor is the 
 fourth one mentioned the free competition of the market. 
 
 In this connection we mean by the market, not a particular 
 place for buying and selling, but the general field within which the 
 forces determining the price of a particular commodity operate. For 
 some commodities, especially perishable ones, like fresh milk and 
 cream, the market is distinctly a local one. In the case of great 
 staple commodities like wheat and cotton, the market is a world 
 market, for it is impossible that the prices of wheat or cotton in 
 Europe should differ for any considerable time from their prices 
 in America by more than the expense of transportation. So-called
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 159 
 
 "international" securities, such as government bonds and the 
 stocks and bonds of certain great corporations, afford even a better 
 example of goods for which the market is a world market. Some 
 commodities are used only in a particular locality or country, 
 although produced in many different places. The American con- 
 sular reports frequently contain advice to American manufac- 
 turers as to special kinds and varieties of goods used in different 
 foreign countries. The cotton mills of England, Germany, and 
 the United States all make special grades of cotton cloth designed 
 especially for the Oriental market. Much more numerous, how- 
 ever, are the goods which, although of wide and general consump- 
 tion, are produced in but few localities. This is especially evi- 
 dent in the case of agricultural and mineral products, but it is 
 increasingly noticeable in manufactures. 
 
 Along with this localization of industry there has been a broad- 
 ening of the field of consumption of many commodities. Among 
 the factors which have contributed to this result may be men- 
 tioned, first, the increasingly cosmopolitan character of modern 
 life, a result of more generally diffused facilities for higher edu- 
 cation, as well as of the growing ease of travel and communica- 
 tion, and secondly, what has been called the "standardization of 
 taste," a result in part of modern advertising methods and of 
 the standardization of products which is one of the fundamental 
 features of modern machine industry. Notwithstanding the bar- 
 riers which still exist in the form of protective tariffs and local 
 prejudices, a dominant feature of modern markets is the localiza- 
 tion of production and the extension of the field of consumption. 
 
 The Conditions of Competitive Valuation. It is often assumed 
 that competitive prices are in some way "natural" and right 
 prices. To guard against this error it is only necessary to remind 
 ourselves that competition operates under the limitations imposed 
 by the fundamental institutions of the existing social order. In 
 the analysis of valuation under purely competitive conditions, we 
 shall assume the existence of private property, since, strictly 
 speaking, it is the property rights in various goods that constitute 
 the things that are bought and sold. It is necessary, also, to as- 
 sume the existence of the right of free contract the right of
 
 160 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 each man to sell for what he can get, and to buy for as little as he 
 can bargain to pay. So far as society limits the right of private 
 property and the right of free contract, it alters the conditions 
 of competition and correspondingly affects the values fixed by 
 competition. 
 
 Supply and Demand. The only goods which are valued in the 
 market are economic goods; that is, such goods as combine the 
 characteristics of utility and scarcity. This statement is a truism, 
 for no one will pay for things that he does not want or for things 
 that can be obtained freely. Utility and scarcity affect the mar- 
 ket value of goods through the operation of the forces of demand 
 and supply. The general "common-sense" explanation of the 
 valuation of goods takes the form of the statement that values are 
 determined by supply and demand. When rightly interpreted, 
 this statement cannot be criticised, but it is often used in an en- 
 tirely erroneous sense. Producers do not usually throw their 
 goods unreservedly on the market, accepting any price that can 
 be got for them, nor do consumers generally demand definite 
 amounts of goods, without reference to the price of them. An 
 entirely accurate statement, and one that is less apt to be misin- 
 terpreted, is that prices are among the factors determining supply 
 and demand. It may seem, accordingly, something like arguing 
 in a circle to attempt to explain value by using the formula of 
 supply and demand; but the fact is that the explanation of value 
 is to be sought in the action of mutually dependent forces, rather 
 than in any one principle. Our next task is, therefore, the analy- 
 sis of supply and demand. 
 
 The Nature of Demand. Mere desire for a commodity is not 
 demand for it. The desire of the poor man for the counterpart 
 of his wealthy neighbor's automobile is in no sense demand. 
 Effective demand is sometimes defined as desire coupled with the 
 ability to pay. But to make demand really effective there must 
 be added to these the inclination to buy: desire must be intense 
 enough to lead to purchase. As has been shown in a previous 
 chapter, intensity of desire cannot be thought of as existing for 
 a commodity in general, but only for particular units of a com- 
 modity. The intensity of one's desire for an additional unit of a
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 161 
 
 commodity depends upon the extent to which one's wants are 
 satisfied by one's existing supply of that commodity. This is the 
 same as saying that the intensity of our desire for a commodity 
 is measured by its marginal utility. 
 
 Every person tends to keep the marginal utilities of the differ- 
 ent kinds of commodities he consumes equal. Either by a con- 
 scious balancing against each other of the pleasures to be ob- 
 tained from two or more possible purchases, or oftener, by simply 
 buying the things which we want more than we want other things, 
 we tend to keep our unsatisfied wants in a state of approximately 
 equal intensity. Every person thus has what has been called a 
 margin of consumption, which is measured by the utility that 
 would be obtained by the expenditure of another dollar (or any 
 other small amount of money) for any one of the things that he 
 consumes. An important thing in the explanation of demand is 
 the fact that this margin of consumption differs for different per- 
 sons, as well as for the same persons at different times. An 
 individual's margin of consumption depends primarily on his 
 income, but also on his tastes and habits, his instinct for saving, 
 and the extent to which he estimates present wants more highly 
 than future wants. Then, too, one's desires are constantly chang- 
 ing under the influence of whim, fashion, satiety, sellers' adver- 
 tising, education, travel, reading, and new experiences of all kinds. 
 Expenditures of all sorts are thus called into being by the neces- 
 sity of maintaining the level of the margin of consumption. The 
 advertiser may succeed in making us think that we want his goods 
 more than we want other things that we could purchase with the 
 same amount of money; reading may so stimulate our desire for 
 travel that we are willing to curtail other expenditures in order 
 to secure it. Education ought to affect the quality as well as 
 the quantity of our wants. 
 
 But even if our desires were constant, changes in prices would 
 in themselves effect continual alterations in the proportions of 
 various things that make up our purchases. If the price of a 
 commodity decreases to such an extent that an additional dollar's 
 worth has a utility greater than our margin of consumption, we 
 normally purchase it. If the price rises, we normally curtail our 
 
 M
 
 162 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 expenditures for this particular commodity, and may even, under 
 some circumstances, become sellers of it (as in the case of the 
 householder who has bought a large supply of coal at five dollars 
 per ton, and who, when the price rises to ten dollars, is willing to 
 sell part of it). Some of the foregoing discussion may seem to 
 be a statement of what is obvious and commonplace, but the neg- 
 lect of these seemingly obvious factors is responsible for more 
 than one erroneous explanation of the way in which values are 
 determined. 
 
 The Demand Curve. The relations between price and de- 
 mand may be shown concretely by the analysis of the condi- 
 tions in a hypothetical 
 market. Imagine the case 
 of an isolated community 
 in which there is consider- 
 able use of wood as a fuel. 
 The conditions might be 
 such as are represented 
 graphically in Figure i. In 
 this diagram distances 
 measured from O along 
 the horizontal line OX represent different amounts of wood, while 
 distances measured vertically from the line OX represent prices. 
 Assuming that the conditions of demand were as represented in 
 the diagram, if the price of wood were MP dollars a cord, OM 
 cords of wood would be bought. If MP represents a relatively 
 high price for wood, this might mean that many families would 
 choose to go without wood, using other kinds of fuel instead. 
 Others would be content with a scanty supply. If, however, the 
 price were reduced to M'P' dollars per cord, some of the families 
 who would have refused to buy at the higher price would purchase 
 wood, while others would increase their purchases, so that OM' 
 cords would be bought. Similarly, at the price M"P", the amount 
 bought would be OM" cords. Other possible prices might be in- 
 dicated on the diagram, so that, in general, the curve DD' (which 
 we may call the demand curve) represents the relation between 
 price and the amount demanded. The rectangle OM'P'A' rep-
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 163 
 
 resents the total amount the community pays for wood when the 
 price is M'P', just as the rectangle OM"P"A" represents the 
 total amount paid when the price is M"P". It often happens 
 that this total value is less when the price is low than when the 
 price is high, although the amount bought at the lower price may 
 be double or treble the amount that would be bought at the higher 
 price. This means not only a better satisfaction of wants with a 
 smaller expenditure of money, but also that more money is avail- 
 able for the purchase of other things; so that there is a general 
 lowering in the margin of consumption a better satisfaction of 
 wants in general. If, however, the relations between price and 
 demand were such that the rectangle OM"P"A" would be larger 
 than the rectangle OM'P'A', the existence of the lower price 
 would necessitate curtailing expenditures for other things. This 
 might involve only a decreased use of substitutes for wood, such 
 as coal; more often, however, it would mean a diminished con- 
 sumption of a number of other things. But any decrease in the 
 price of any commodity of general consumption, other things re- 
 maining equal, means always a lowering of the margin of con- 
 Sumption of all persons increasing their use of the commodity in 
 question. For the lower price would not be accompanied by the 
 purchase of a larger amount of wood if the additional wood did 
 not satisfy more intense wants than would other things that might 
 be purchased with the money. 
 
 In this way the demand for any one commodity is affected by 
 the demand for any other commodity. The competition of the 
 market thus embraces not only the buying and selling of a given 
 commodity (like wood) , but also the buying and selling of all com- 
 modities. In this sense the wood dealers compete with the grocers 
 and the tailors, as well as with coal dealers and with each other. 
 
 The Elasticity of Demand. By the elasticity of demand we 
 mean the extent to which the amounts demanded vary with changes 
 in price. In every family in poor or moderate circumstances 
 the housewife carefully economizes in the use of eggs during 
 periods when they are high in price, using them more freely when 
 the price is lower. In such a case the demand for eggs is an elastic 
 one. Relatively inelastic are the demands of most families for
 
 1 64 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 
 
 FIG. 2 
 
 such things as flour and salt. Other commodities, such as sugar, 
 
 may occupy an intermediate position. Figures 2 and 3 repre- 
 sent, respectively, 
 elastic and inelas- 
 tic conditions of 
 demand. With- 
 out giving further 
 concrete exam- 
 ples, the follow- 
 ing propositions 
 respecting elas- 
 ticity of demand 
 maybe stated: 
 (i) Demand for 
 necessities is in 
 
 general less elastic than demand for luxuries. (2) Demand for 
 
 commodities the use of which constitutes a habit is less elastic 
 
 than demand for commodi- Y 
 
 ties the use of which is gen- 
 erally a matter of conscious 
 
 decision. (3) The more 
 
 adequate the substitutes for 
 
 a particular commodity the 
 
 more elastic will be the 
 
 demand for it. (4) The 
 
 demand of persons of large 
 
 income is less elastic than 
 
 that of persons in poor or 
 
 moderate circumstances. (5) 
 
 A corollary of proposition 
 
 Jour is that the higher the 
 
 general level of well-being 
 
 in a community, the less elastic will be the demand for most 
 
 commodities. 
 
 Consumers' Surplus. Whatever the price of a competitively produced 
 commodity may be, there are almost always some buyers who would have 
 paid more if it had been necessary. Referring to Figure i, if the price is 
 
 
 
 M' 
 
 FIG. 3
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 165 
 
 M'P', those who are just willing to pay that price, who would either have 
 bought less or bought none if the price had been higher, may be called the 
 marginal buyers. These are relatively few in number, however, as compared 
 with those who would have bought even if the price had been higher. The 
 utility of the marginal purchases to the buyers is but little more than the 
 utility of other things that could have been bought with the same amount of 
 money : in such cases the utility of the purchase only about equals the sacri- 
 fice involved. In the case of all other purchases, however, there is a surplus 
 of utilty over costs (whether costs are measured as money costs or as the 
 utility of the other possible purchases which are given up) which is called 
 consumers' surplus (or sometimes consumers' rent, or buyers' gains). It 
 might be supposed at first thought that if the price were, for example, M'P' 
 (Fig. i), the area included between the horizontal line A'P' and the curve 
 DP' would represent consumers' surplus. This is not exactly true, however, 
 and that for two reasons: in the first place, the satisfaction of additional 
 wants which a lower price makes possible may make the more important 
 wants less intense. A man might be willing to give ten dollars for a cord of 
 wood in order that at least one room in his house could be heated during the 
 winter. He might also be willing to give seven dollars a cord for two cords, 
 so as to heat two rooms, but the heating of the second room might render the 
 heating of the first room less important to him. He might not be willing, 
 for example, to give ten dollars plus seven dollars in order to have the two 
 rooms heated. In the second place, utility itself is to a large extent affected 
 by price. So far as our purchases satisfy what has been called the desire for 
 distinction, or represent what Professor Veblen has called "conspicuous 
 consumption," a lowering of the price of a commodity would lessen its utility 
 to us. The successful production of artificial diamonds at a low cost would 
 lessen the desire which most people have for natural ones. If touring cars 
 were less an indication of one's ability to spend money freely, they would be 
 less esteemed by a good many people. On the other hand, it might occur in 
 some cases that a certain amount of decrease in the price of a commodity, 
 permitting a more general consumption of it, would increase the esteem in 
 which it is held by those who are glad to follow fads. In general, we must say 
 that even if we had absolutely complete statistics of the actual relation of 
 prices to demand, consumers' surplus would still be an incommensurable 
 thing. It is nevertheless a real thing, and is especially significant as con- 
 stituting one of the differences between real income and money incomes. 
 It should be noted, however, that consumers' surplus relates only to one's 
 consumption of a particular commodity, taken by itself, for as we have seen, 
 the amount which we are willing to spend in the purchase of any one com- 
 modity depends not only on the price of that commodity, but also on the price 
 of the other commodities that make up our purchases. The surpluses which 
 a consumer gets in his different lines of consumption cannot be added to- 
 gether to form a total.
 
 1 66 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The Nature of Supply. The amount of goods that will be sup- 
 plied in a given market at a given time depends, like the amount 
 demanded, on the price. "Forced sales," in which goods are 
 offered for whatever can be got for them, form about the only 
 important exception. The effect of price on supply varies, how- 
 ever, according to the length of time that is taken into considera- 
 tion. The work that is being done to-day in the extension of old 
 factories and the building of new ones, the construction of rail- 
 ways, the taking up of new land, is based on estimates of future 
 prices, the present prices of agricultural and manufactured prod- 
 ucts and of railway transportation being of significance only so 
 far as they indicate what future prices will be. The merchant's 
 stock in trade is bought on an estimate of future business condi- 
 tions; the amount of land the farmer allots to wheat and corn, 
 respectively, depends on his estimate of the relative prices the 
 two will bring after the harvest. In a similar way the amounts of 
 goods that can be supplied to the market to-day are limited by 
 the estimates which business men and farmers have made in the 
 past of the prices which buyers are willing to pay to-day. It 
 would be possible, though not necessary for our purposes, to ana- 
 lyze the way in which the amount of the capital and labor which 
 have thus been applied to the production of things that will 
 satisfy present wants was partially determined by conditions which 
 existed still farther back in the past, and so on in an indefinitely 
 receding series. The amount of goods available for the market 
 of to-day is thus limited not only by past estimates and conditions, 
 but also by present estimates of future conditions. Every seller 
 has the option of selling at the present price or of waiting for 
 possibly higher future prices an option which is limited only by 
 the perishability of his goods and the urgency of his need for 
 money. And the most urgent need for money does not neces- 
 sarily force an immediate sale if his opinion as to the future 
 value of his goods is a reasonable one, for in this case it is 
 usually easy to borrow money on the strength of the marketable 
 value of the goods. 
 
 The Supply Curve. In the analysis of the conditions of sup- 
 ply existing in a particular market at a particular time we do not
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 167 
 
 M 
 
 M' M" 
 FIG. 4 
 
 have to take account of the limitations imposed by the forms which 
 productive efforts have taken in the past. At any given time a 
 certain definite amount of a commodity is available for the market: 
 this forms what may be called 
 the potential supply. The pro- 
 portion of this potential supply 
 that sellers will be willing to part 
 with at a particular time will de- 
 pend primarily on the prices they 
 can get. If the price of a unit 
 of a commodity is M' P' (Fig. 4), 
 the sellers will be willing to sell 
 a certain number of units of it, 
 which may be represented by 
 OM'. If the price were as low as PM , however, some sellers 
 would prefer to wait for higher prices, the amount thus withheld 
 from the market being represented by MM'. At the price M" P", 
 however, an additional supply (M'M") of the commodity would be 
 forthcoming from sellers who were not tempted by the price M'P'. 
 In general, the supply curve SS' represents the relations between 
 price and the amount that will be supplied in a particular market 
 and at a particular time. 
 
 The Determination of Price. The foregoing discussion of the 
 TT nature of demand and 
 
 of supply makes it pos- 
 sible to advance another 
 step in our analysis of 
 the determination of 
 price, by asking our- 
 selves what will be the 
 result of the simultane- 
 ous operation of the 
 
 forces of demand and 
 
 f 
 
 supply. This condition 
 is represented graphic- 
 ally in Figure 5, where the demand curve and supply curve are 
 combined in one diagram. If the curve DD' represents the 
 
 M' 
 
 M 
 
 FIG. 5
 
 1 68 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 potential demand in a particular market at a particular time, and 
 the curve SS' represents the potential supply, the price which 
 would be fixed by the free working of competitive forces would 
 be PM, located at the point where the two curves cross. At this 
 point demand and supply are equal, both being represented by 
 OM . It is impossible that the price should be fixed at any other 
 point, M' P', for example. For if M"Q be drawn so as to equal 
 M' P', it will be evident that at this price OM" units will be de- 
 manded, while only OM' units will be supplied. Most of the 
 buyers, however, are willing to pay more than M' P' if necessary, 
 so that in order to secure their share they will bid the price up 
 until the supply equals the demand. This is what John Stuart 
 Mill meant when he said that "value always adjusts itself in such 
 a manner that the demand is equal to the supply," a state- 
 ment which has often been misinterpreted, and consequently un- 
 justifiably criticised. 
 
 Producers' Surplus. Just as the area APD (Fig. 5) has sometimes been 
 considered, not altogether accurately, to represent a " Consumers' Surplus" 
 (of utility over costs) , so the area APS has been considered to correspond to 
 what has been called " Producers' Surplus " or " Sellers' Gains." This sur- 
 plus should not be thought of as corresponding to the actual profits of the 
 sellers; that is, as being in any way a surplus of value over and above the 
 expenses of production. It cannot be too strongly emphasized that the 
 analysis of demand and supply thus far presented relates only to the condi- 
 tions existing in a particular market at a particular time. All that we can say 
 is that when OM units are sold at the price of MP per unit, the total re- 
 ceipts of the sellers are represented by the rectangle OMPA ; while the area 
 OMPS represents what they would have been willing to sell the same 
 amount of goods for, had they not been able to get a larger return. There 
 is, as we shall see, a relation between the prices of things and the expense 
 of producing them, when a considerable period of time is taken into con- 
 sideration. At any given time, however, sellers are mainly governed by the 
 relative profitableness of selling at existing prices or waiting for higher 
 ones. The only kind of surplus which the area APS represents is an intan- 
 gible, hypothetical thing. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Is there such a thing as "intrinsic value"? What is usually meant 
 when the expression is used? 
 
 2. How would you apply the concept of marginal utility to a non-divisible 
 good, like a house ?
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 169 
 
 3. Does the tendency of each individual to maintain the equilibrium of 
 his margin of consumption result in the maximum satisfaction of his wants? 
 
 4. What relation is there between the amounts which a college student 
 pays for room rent, for food, for clothing, for books, and for athletics ? 
 
 5. Which of your customary purchases would you still make if prices 
 were doubled ? Which would you curtail ? Which would you omit ? 
 
 6. Illustrate the propositions relating to elasticity of demand (p. 164) by 
 concrete examples. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BOHM-BAWERK, E. VON. Positive Theory of Capital, Book IV, Chaps. 
 
 I-VI. 
 
 CARVER, T. N. Distribution of Wealth, Chap. I. 
 
 CUNYNGHAME, HENRY. Geometrical Political Economy, Chaps. Ill and IV. 
 HADLEY, A. T. Economics, Chap. III. 
 HOBSON, J. A. Economics of Distribution, Chaps. I and II. 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 4th ed., Book III and Book 
 
 V, Chaps. I and II. Or [abridged] Economics of Industry, 3d ed., 
 
 Book III and Book V, Chaps. I and II. 
 
 MILL, J. S. Principles of Political Economy, Book III, Chaps. I and II. 
 WIESER, F. VON. Natural Value, Book II, Chaps. I-V.
 
 CHAPTER XII 
 VALUE AND PRICE (Continued) 
 
 SOME of the most important factors in the determination of ex- 
 change values are not revealed by an analysis of the conditions 
 existing at a particular time. We have assumed, for example, 
 an existing potential demand and an existing potential supply, 
 and have shown how these result in the equilibrium of actual 
 demand and supply at a certain price. An explanation of why 
 potential demand and potential supply are as they are necessi- 
 tates taking a considerable period of time into consideration. 
 The demand side of this particular problem need not detain us. 
 It has already been suggested that demand will change with 
 changes in incomes, tastes, fashions, and the like. The effect 
 of these influences is so obvious that it may be taken for granted. 
 With reference to the other side of the problem, however, it has 
 been pointed out that the potential supply of the present is lim- 
 ited by conditions set by past industry. The amounts of dif- 
 ferent kinds of consumption goods that are ready for present 
 use depends upon the direction which the work of production has 
 taken in the past. What, in the long run, is the relation between 
 supply and value ? To answer this question we shall have to 
 push our analysis somewhat farther. 
 
 Normal Value. The dominant motive that guides farmers and 
 business men in their investments of labor and capital is the de- 
 sire for money profits. By profits we mean in this connection 
 the difference between the expense involved in producing goods 
 and the money that can be obtained for them. If it were always 
 an easy matter for business men to change their interests and 
 their energies from one line of production to another, and if 
 capital and labor could likewise be freely transferred from one 
 undertaking to another, it is hard to see how profits in any one 
 competitive business could be for any length of time much higher 
 
 170
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 171 
 
 than in other competitive businesses. Managerial ability, labor, 
 and capital would gravitate always toward those employments 
 which promise the greatest profits. The effect would be a con- 
 tinual tendency toward equality of advantage in different lines 
 of business. This does not mean necessarily an equality of 
 profits as between individuals in any given line of business, for 
 the amount of profits depends largely upon the skill and enter- 
 prise of the individual business man. In a state of free compe- 
 tition, with managerial ability as free in its selection of oppor- 
 tunities as we have assumed, the profits of any business would 
 hardly be larger, for any period of time, than the business man 
 could get as salary by working for others for if working for 
 others offered a greater return than assuming the risks of busi- 
 ness for himself, he would naturally choose the salaried position, 
 and -vice versa. Purely competitive profits, under conditions of 
 absolute "fluidity" of business ability, of labor, and of capital, 
 would thus tend to adjust themselves according to the ability of 
 the individual business man; that is, to equal what we shall later 
 describe as the "wages of management." If we include the 
 value of the business man's services among the expenses of pro- 
 duction, we may, obviously, state the tendency which we have 
 described as a tendency toward the equality of the prices received 
 for the products of any particular business and the expenses of 
 producing them. 
 
 The assumptions we have made do not, however, exactly cor- 
 respond to the conditions of actual business. Managerial ability, 
 labor, and capital are all specialized to a greater or less extent, 
 so that they cannot be changed from one employment to another 
 without loss of efficiency. But it is not necessary for the valid- 
 ity of our analysis that all managerial ability, all labor, and all 
 capital should be fluid enough to change from industry to indus- 
 try economically. There are always a certain number of business 
 men who are anxiously watching for the most inviting busi- 
 ness opportunities; there is always a certain amount of labor 
 awaiting the most remunerative employment, and there is always 
 a certain amount of money awaiting investment in those forms 
 of capital goods which produce the greatest value. These facts
 
 172 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 are enough to give substantial truth to the statement that in any 
 competitive industry the price of the commodity produced tends 
 to equal the cost of producing it. When the price of bicycles 
 was high, as compared with the expense of producing them, 
 existing bicycle factories were extended and new ones were built. 
 The supply of bicycles was thus so increased that they could not 
 be sold except at a much lower price. On this account and be- 
 cause of the cessation of demand, the profits in the manufacture 
 of bicycles became relatively low, and many former bicycle fac- 
 tories are now used for other purposes. If the excess of the 
 price of wheat over the expense of producing it promises to be 
 greater than the excess of the price of corn over the expense of 
 producing it, farmers will raise less corn and more wheat, and the 
 result will be higher prices for corn and lower prices for wheat. 
 
 On account of this tendency of prices to equal the expenses of 
 production, the expense of producing a unit of a commodity is 
 called its normal value. It must be clearly understood that 
 normal values relate only to a tendency not to the actual 
 prices of the market. 
 
 Different Conditions of Supply. The strength of the tend- 
 ency of actual competitive values to equal normal values depends 
 upon the length of the period of time that is taken into considera- 
 tion. The longer the period of time, the larger will be the pro- 
 portion of managerial ability, labor, and capital that can be trans- 
 ferred from one industry to another. To build and to equip new 
 factories and to extend old ones takes time; the supply of skilled 
 labor in any occupation can often be increased but slowly, for 
 many trades involve an apprenticeship of three or more years. 
 In the undertakings that are becoming less profitable, although 
 capital specialized in the form of machines may not be useful for 
 other purposes, yet such machines need not be replaced as they 
 wear out; while a skilled laborer cannot take up another trade 
 without loss of efficiency, yet the incoming supply of laborers 
 may begin their apprenticeship in those occupations in which 
 there is a greater demand for labor. 
 
 While the conditions of long-period supply are thus such as to 
 result in a constant tendency toward the equalization of normal
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 173 
 
 value and market value, this tendency may never work itself out 
 completely. For market values themselves are constantly chang- 
 ing under the influence of changing demand. The goal toward 
 which productive effort is working is a constantly shifting one. 
 Moreover, the expense of production itself often depends upon 
 the amount produced. The efforts of entrepreneurs to adjust 
 production to prices result inevitably in a readjustment of the 
 conditions that determine the expenses of production. Three 
 forms of productive undertaking may be here distinguished: 
 those in which increased production is accomplished with in- 
 creasing, decreasing, or constant expense. 
 
 If transportation facilities and other controlling conditions 
 remain constant, the amount of wheat raised in the United States 
 cannot be substantially increased without resort to lands less 
 well adapted to the production of wheat, or the more intensive 
 cultivation of lands already in use. Either alternative means 
 (as will be shown in a later chapter in more detail) the use of 
 relatively more labor and capital in producing the additional 
 wheat than was required for the wheat produced under the for- 
 mer conditions. This fact means that the production of wheat 
 cannot be substantially increased except at an increased expense 
 per bushel. When this condition of increasing expense is met 
 with, and it holds true generally in agriculture, normal 
 value is fixed by the expense of production of the most expensive 
 part of the supply. That is, normal value tends to equal margi- 
 nal expense. If the price of the product is not high enough to 
 repay the cultivation of the poorest lands used, they will cease to 
 be cultivated. If the price of the product is appreciably higher 
 than the marginal expense, farmers will find it profitable to push 
 cultivation still farther, up to the point where the new marginal 
 expense equals the price. 
 
 In many manufacturing and commercial businesses, however, 
 it is cheaper to produce on a large scale, so that an increase in 
 amount produced means a relatively smaller expense per unit of 
 product. In such cases a general increase in production means 
 a decrease in the normal value of the product. At any definite 
 time a given product will be produced by a number of different
 
 174 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 establishments of varying grades of efficiency, and if these are all 
 to continue in operation, the price received for the product must 
 be sufficient to cover the expenses of production of the least effi- 
 cient of them. It is the supply coming from these least efficient 
 establishments that adjusts itself most accurately to changes in 
 price. From this point of view, we may say that in manufac- 
 tures, as in agriculture, normal values equal marginal expenses. 
 But this fact is not very significant, for as soon as we take a longer 
 period of time into consideration, we recognize that the higher 
 price which enables the marginal establishment to produce at 
 all, also enables the better establishments to produce on a larger 
 scale. The reduced expenses of production necessitate, through 
 competition, a lowering of the price, and the less efficient estab- 
 lishments find themselves forced out by the very conditions that 
 permitted them to produce at all. From the long-time point of 
 view, it is minimum, rather than maximum, expenses of produc- 
 tion that measure normal values in industries of decreasing ex- 
 penses. There is by this process a continual elimination of the 
 inefficient producers and a continual insistence upon higher stand- 
 ards of efficiency on the part of the superior producers. The 
 minimum expenses of production to-day become the marginal 
 expenses of production to-morrow. 
 
 The condition of decreasing expenses dominates in most of the 
 great factory industries of the present. 1 Its effect is sometimes 
 offset by the increased cost of raw material produced under con- 
 ditions of increasing expenses. The diminution of expenses 
 which accompanies an increase in the amount of the business is 
 of special significance in railway transportation, and in a number 
 of other monopolistic businesses. The telephone business, how- 
 ever, is alleged to be subject to conditions of increasing expenses. 
 Some writers hold that the dominance of the condition of de- 
 creasing expenses in any business is enough to make it monopo- 
 listic in tendency. 
 
 In many hand industries, such as tailoring and cigar making, 
 the expense of production per unit does not vary to any great 
 
 1 Some qualifications of this statement are suggested in the following section 
 on "Constant and Variable Expenses."
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 FIG. i 
 
 extent with the amount produced. Figures i, 2, and 3 illustrate 
 supply under the conditions of increasing, decreasing, and con- 
 stant expenses, respectively : 
 These diagrams illustrate the 
 relations between price and 
 supply when a considerable 
 period of time is taken into 
 account and must be carefully 
 distinguished from the supply 
 curve described in the preced- j 
 ing chapter, which related 
 only to the conditions of 
 supply at a particular time. 
 The "supply" illustrated in 
 these long-period supply 
 curves is about the same as 
 the "potential supply" of 
 the preceding chapter. 
 
 Constant and Variable Ex- 
 penses. There is no better 
 illustration of the necessity 
 of keeping definite periods of 
 time in mind when discussing 
 problems relating to valuation r 
 than that furnished by the 
 problem of the apportionment 
 of specific expenses of produc- 
 tion to particular units of 
 products. In almost any 
 industrial establishment, any 
 increase in product will be 
 attended by some specific in- 
 
 
 1 
 
 P' 
 
 MM' A 
 FIG. a 
 
 P' 
 
 M 
 
 M' 
 
 FIG. 3 
 
 crease in expenses: more raw 
 
 material and more labor will 
 
 be used, possibly more power; although the increased expenses 
 
 for labor and power may not be proportionate to the increase 
 
 in production. Such expenses are called variable expenses, and
 
 176 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 are to be contrasted with constant expenses, which remain 
 approximately the same, no matter what the amount pro- 
 duced is. The interest on the capital invested in the factory 
 building and its equipment of machinery is a constant expense; 
 the expense of management and general office expenses will be 
 increased but slightly by an increase in the annual product of an 
 establishment. It is often assumed that wherever only a part 
 of the expenses varies with the amount produced, the industry is 
 ipso facto one of decreasing expenses. Whether this assumption 
 holds true or not depends on the length of the period of time we 
 take into consideration. It is true that factories are built with 
 a certain maximum capacity, and until that maximum capacity 
 is utilized, production may be increased without a proportionate 
 increase in expenditure. When the maximum is reached, how- 
 ever, more equipment, and often more buildings, will be needed 
 before there can be a further increase in product. There is often 
 a certain most efficient size of plant; an increase in business be- 
 yond the capacity of the most efficient size of plant necessitates 
 either a curtailing of the business or a duplication of the plant. 
 When business conditions are such as to warrant temporarily 
 
 pushing the output 
 of a plant beyond 
 its normal capacity, 
 the result usually 
 is, as every manu- 
 facturer knows, that 
 this increased out- 
 put is produced at 
 relatively increased 
 expenses of produc- 
 
 O 1 jf j/"^ X tion. Many seem- 
 
 FIG. 4 ingly constant 
 
 expenditures (like 
 
 interest on the cost of the plant) are variable in the long run. 
 Such expenditures increase, but only at considerable intervals 
 of time. A supply curve corresponding to the conditions of 
 production in such a business might be something like Figure 4.
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 177 
 
 When the product reaches OM units, and again when it reaches 
 OM' units, fresh investments of large amounts of capital are neces- 
 sary. From the long-time point of view, such a business might 
 very possibly be one of approximately constant expenses; although 
 of course the other economies of large-scale production may be 
 sufficient to bring them under the rule of decreasing expenses. 
 The problem which the economist has to deal with here is analo- 
 gous to the difficult one which the accountant has to face in fac- 
 tory cost keeping. Careful analysis of the relations of constant 
 and variable expenses in different modern businesses must pre- 
 cede any broad generalization. 
 
 Joint Expenses of Production. When the production of one 
 commodity is inevitably accompanied by the production of one 
 or more other commodities, it is often impossible to assign a defi- 
 nite part of the total expense of production to any one of the com- 
 modities. It is obviously impossible to separate the expenses 
 of producing tenderloin steaks from the expenses of producing 
 soup bones, or either one of these from the expenses of producing 
 hides. Mutton and wool, cotton and cotton seed, coal gas and 
 coke, are familiar examples of commodities produced under 
 conditions of joint expense. Modern methods for the utilization 
 of industrial by-products have greatly increased the list of com- 
 modities produced under conditions of joint expense. Such com- 
 modities have only a collective normal value, which is equal to 
 the joint expenses of production. The potential supply is governed 
 by the total price which the producer thinks he can get for the 
 joint products, as compared with the joint expenses of produc- 
 ing them. The division of the total price into specific prices for 
 the separate commodities is determined by the potential supply 
 and by the conditions of demand that exist at any one time for 
 the separate products. 
 
 The Surplus of Bargaining. Demand and supply do not al- 
 ways fix price at a definite point. The price of horses of any 
 given grade, for example, is fixed only approximately by market 
 conditions. In the sale of a horse there is room for consider- 
 able latitude of opinion as to the price that should be paid. If 
 the lowest price that the seller will take is considerably below
 
 178 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the highest price that the buyer will give, just where between 
 these limits the actual price will be finally fixed will depend 
 upon the relative skill at bargaining of the seller and buyer. In 
 the case of a horse trade, this opportunity for the "higgling of 
 the market" has become proverbial, but in many other kinds 
 of exchanges the efficient bargainer has an opportunity to get 
 for himself a surplus above his minimum selling price, or below 
 his maximum buying price. Real estate transactions furnish 
 a good example. In the case of the great commodities of the 
 world market, like wheat, cotton, and iron, the price is set so 
 accurately by market conditions that the gains of bargaining 
 are relatively small. In general, the wider the market, the more 
 general the use of the commodity, the greater the ease with which the 
 commodity can be sorted into standard grades (as in the case of 
 wheat and cotton), the more accurately will competitive forces fix a 
 definite price. Goods which cannot be standardized, each unit of 
 which possesses some unique qualities, give most scope for the varia- 
 tions in the valuations of individual buyers and sellers. In such 
 cases supply and demand do not fix a price point, but only cer- 
 tain limits within which the price must fall. The widening of 
 the market, however, and the increasing standardization of 
 commodities an effect of machine production are bringing 
 a larger and larger proportion of goods into the field where the 
 uniform market valuations dominate. 
 
 Non-reproducible Goods. Some economic writers have made 
 a special class of such goods as great works of art. These are 
 absolutely unique, in that no copy can have anything like the 
 value of the original. The price of such non-reproducible goods 
 has an upper limit fixed by the highest subjective valuation set 
 upon it by any possible buyer. The lower limit will be either 
 the seller's own subjective valuation, or the second highest valu- 
 ation set by any competing buyer, according as one or the other 
 of these two is the higher. Between the upper and lower limit 
 the exact fixing of the price is a matter of pure bargaining. Such 
 cases should not be confused with ordinary monopoly price, as 
 has been done by some writers. The products of almost all the 
 industrial handicrafts, as well as the products of the avowedly
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 
 
 I 79 
 
 artistic pursuits, possess a non-reproducible element of individ- 
 uality, that removes them to a greater or less extent from the 
 operations of the law of normal value. A commodity may pos- 
 sess this quality of uniqueness to such an extent that it is not 
 affected at all by the forces determining the value of the general 
 class of goods to which it belongs, and in this case its owner may 
 be said to have a monopoly of it. But it is better to look upon 
 the valuations of such non-reproducible goods as determined by 
 individual valuations and the process of bargaining. The "nor- 
 mal " price of such goods is simply the highest price that can be 
 got for them a statement which does not hold true of most 
 monopoly goods. For monopoly goods are not necessarily unique 
 or non-reproducible. They differ from ordinary competitive 
 goods, however, in that they cannot be reproduced except by 
 the monopolist. 
 
 Monopoly Values. The subject of monopoly price will be 
 discussed in connection with an analysis of the general subject 
 of monopoly in a later chapter. It is sufficient in this connection 
 to note that the monopolist gets a special power over the price 
 of his product through his ability to control the supply of it. 
 The monopolist, like any other seller, seeks to get the price that 
 yields the greatest net returns, but unlike the competitive seller, 
 he is not hampered by an inability to fix the price very much 
 above the cost of production. 
 
 Retail Prices. The retail prices paid by the individual con- 
 sumer do not always respond to the variations in wholesale prices 
 brought about by changes in supply and demand. There are 
 sometimes tacit or explicit local price agreements between local 
 merchants, which apply even to competitively produced goods. 
 Some retailers consistently sell a few kinds of goods at less than 
 cost to attract custom for the goods on which they may make a 
 profit. Merchants who make a specialty of a high class of goods, 
 and thus cater to a wealthy clientele, are apt to exact higher prices 
 for ordinary goods than do those merchants who have to deal with 
 a poorer class of customers. Custom has more effect on retail 
 than on wholesale prices. The prices of various articles sold as 
 "men's furnishing goods" form a good example of the influence
 
 l8o OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of custom. Retail prices are also governed by the value of the 
 coins that are in general use, and are generally expressed in 
 round numbers. In the long run, demand and supply govern 
 retail prices, but they do not set a definite price point so accu- 
 rately as they do in the case of wholesale prices. 
 
 Public Authority and Value. In the middle ages there was 
 considerable speculation by theologians and legists about the 
 subject of "just price" the value at which things ought to 
 exchange for other things. This idea denotes an important 
 difference between the mediaeval and modern concept of value. 
 Professor Ashley has put it clearly in these words: "With Aqui- 
 nas, the greatest of the mediaeval schoolmen, it [value] was some- 
 thing objective; something outside of the will of the individual 
 purchaser or seller; something attached to the thing itself, exist- 
 ing whether he liked it or not, and that he ought to recognize. 
 And as experience showed that individuals could not be trusted 
 thus to admit the real value of things, it followed that it was the 
 duty of the proper authorities of state, town, or gild to step in 
 and determine it, and what the just and reasonable price really 
 was." This "just and reasonable price" was very often thought 
 to be that price which would afford a reasonable compensation 
 for the labor of the producer. When in more modern times 
 theological speculations began to yield precedence to inquiries 
 into "natural laws," the idea of just price was supplanted by 
 the idea of "natural price." Sometimes this was interpreted as 
 determined by the value of the labor put into a commodity (this 
 was the dominant idea during the eighteenth century), but the 
 growth of capitalistic production necessitated the recognition of 
 the other elements in the expense of producing a commodity as 
 part of its natural value. Modern economic science, as we have 
 seen, applies the term "normal value" to the expense of produc- 
 ing a thing, but interprets it only as an important factor control- 
 ling the long-period fluctuations of competitive exchange value. 
 The adjective "natural," with its misleading implications, has been 
 abandoned. Yet the competitive system is to-day so thoroughly 
 accepted as the "natural" economic order, that there is, as we 
 have previously noted, a deep-seated conviction that normal
 
 VALUE AND PRICE' l8l 
 
 competitive prices (measured by the expenses of production) 
 are natural and just prices. This conviction is, however, brought 
 face to face with the fact of the growth of a large industrial field 
 in which monopoly, rather than competition, rules. The ques- 
 tion of just price is again a live issue as it was before the growth 
 of the competitive system. Public authority is frequently invoked 
 to insure that the prices fixed by holders of municipal franchises 
 and other monopolists are just and reasonable. The chief fun- 
 damental test which our courts are able to apply to the reason- 
 ableness of any particular price is its conformity to what the price 
 would have been under competitive conditions. Thus it is often 
 asked if a particular monopoly charge gives a more than normal 
 return upon the capital invested. The determination of what 
 the expense of producing a particular commodity or service really 
 is, is often a difficult, or even impossible, task (the distinction 
 between constant and variable expenses being frequently a stum- 
 bling-block), but, given the general acceptance of the competi- 
 tive system, it is hard to see what other standard could be used. 
 Moreover, the general consensus of recent court decisions is that 
 the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments to the Federal Constitu- 
 tion, prohibiting the taking of property without due process of 
 law, prevent federal and state governments from going farther 
 than this in the regulation of monopoly charges. 1 And even this 
 power is not conceded, except in the case of businesses affected 
 with a distinct public interest, such as those conducted by so- 
 called public-service corporations. In fixing prices for its own 
 services, such as postal charges, the government is controlled by 
 other considerations. These will be discussed in the chapters 
 on public finance. 
 
 Imputed Value. The only things to which market valuations 
 
 1 It is the view of some courts that not only concrete physical objects, but also 
 the "franchise value" that has resulted from the ability of a company to charge 
 monopoly prices in the past must be counted as "property" in the meaning of the 
 Constitution. So far as this view governs the public regulation of monopoly 
 prices, it is impossible to reduce them to a competitive standard. It should be 
 possible, however, in any particular case, to prevent any increase in this acquired 
 franchise value; that is, to subject public-service monopolies to competitive 
 standards so far as the increase of their earnings is concerned.
 
 1 82 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 actually apply are the specific units of goods that are actually 
 bought and sold. We are accustomed, however, to impute these 
 market values to all other existing goods of the same kinds. When 
 wheat is sixty cents a bushel, the only bushels of wheat actually 
 valued by the market at that price are the ones actually sold at 
 that price. Yet we impute or ascribe the same value to all other 
 bushels of the potential supply of wheat in the same market. It 
 is obvious that all of the potential supply could not be sold at once 
 except at a very much lower price. Any seller could, however, 
 add a small amount to the supply, without materially affecting 
 the price. Exchange value, as a concrete fact, emerges only in 
 the actual process of exchange. The value imputed to goods 
 not in the actual process of exchange is a hypothetical value: 
 the price which could be obtained for any particular unit of a 
 good under existing market conditions. This concept of im- 
 puted value in economics is in some ways like the concept of 
 potential energy in physics. A body of a given mass raised a 
 certain distance above the earth has a certain amount of poten- 
 tial energy, which, if the body be allowed to fall, will be realized 
 in an equivalent amount of actual energy. To make the analogy 
 between potential energy and potential value complete, how- 
 ever, one would not only have to conceive of the force of gravi- 
 tation as continually fluctuating, but also to imagine that the 
 amount of actual energy realized would be relatively diminished 
 according to the mass of the number of the bodies let fall at any 
 particular time. 
 
 Notwithstanding the hypothetical nature of this imputed 
 value, it is often treated as though it were a real thing. Statis- 
 tical attempts to state the wealth of a nation in terms of dollars 
 and cents are only estimates of the sums of these potential values, 
 and involve the hypothesis stated above. A merchant's inven- 
 tory of his stock in trade is often accompanied by an estimate 
 of its potential value. Whether this value will be realized or 
 not depends upon the constancy of business conditions, the ca- 
 prices of fashion, and whether it can be sold in the regular course 
 of trade or whether it has to be disposed of at a forced sale. A 
 good many kinds of consumption goods, such as household fur-
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 183 
 
 niture, are not customarily thought of by the owner in terms of 
 exchange value. It is often necessary for purposes of taxation 
 to ascribe value to them, but it should be remembered that this 
 imputed value is purely hypothetical. 
 
 The Valuation of Production Goods. In our analysis of ex- 
 change value it has been assumed that the commodities valued 
 were wanted by consumers for the satisfaction of their wants; 
 that is, that they were consumption goods. It is possible to 
 say that producers' goods capital and land have a mar- 
 ginal utility for the producers, which measures the importance 
 attached to the possession of them. While one could thus, with 
 substantial accuracy, include producers' goods in the scope of 
 the foregoing analysis, there is a more instructive way of ap- 
 proaching the problem of the valuation of land and capital. Con- 
 sumption goods have value because they satisfy human wants; 
 that is, they yield an income of satisfactions, while production 
 goods are valued because they have the power of gaining a money 
 income for the owner. Just as the value of consumers' goods 
 varies with the intensity of the wants they satisfy, so the value 
 of producers' goods varies with their power to yield a money 
 income. The valuation of producers' goods will, accordingly, 
 be discussed in the chapters on the rent of land and interest. 
 
 Other Theories of Value. The older economists used to em- 
 phasize the relation between the value of a thing and the amount 
 or the expense of the labor spent in producing it, a relation 
 much closer under the old methods of hand production than it 
 is at present. The development of a systematic labor theory 
 of value was, however, the work of Karl Marx, the founder of 
 modern "scientific" socialism. This theory is, in essence, that 
 labor produces all value and that the interest on capital and the 
 rent of land are deductions from the real wages of labor de- 
 ductions that are made possible only by the existence of the sys- 
 tem of private property in producers' goods. It is so obvious 
 that things do not exchange to-day in proportion to the amount 
 of labor involved in producing them, that to point this out in de- 
 tail, as some economists have done, is unnecessary. Karl Marx 
 reallv meant that labor costs constitute the "natural" values
 
 1 84 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of things, or the ratios at which they ought to exchange. But 
 the only "natural" values that can be recognized from the mod- 
 ern scientific point of view are the values that really exist the 
 actual values of the market. Nor can we say that things ought 
 to exchange in proportion to their labor costs, without begging 
 the whole question in favor of the abolition of private property 
 in land and capital. Moreover, it will be shown later that rent 
 and interest would not be eliminated, although they might be 
 changed in form, by a change from private to common owner- 
 ship of producers' goods. Although the labor theory of value 
 is still held by many followers of Marx, its place in the creed of 
 scientific socialism is diminishing in importance. 
 
 The relation between value and the expenses of production 
 has sometimes been stated in such a way as to lead to the infer- 
 ence that cost of production is the cause of value. The cost of 
 production theory of value, when so stated, is open to much 
 the same objections as the labor theory. Suppose I perfect a 
 machine at the expense of ten thousand dollars which will blow 
 soap bubbles at the rate of a thousand an hour. Will it be worth 
 ten thousand dollars ? Certainly not ; but why not ? The theory 
 of costs will not explain it. To say that the labor and materials 
 have not been wisely used is simply to say that the machine has 
 no value, which is just what we are trying to explain. As a 
 fact, it is not worth ten thousand dollars simply because no one 
 is willing to give ten thousand dollars for it. The expenses of 
 production do not create value, but there is a sense in. which 
 value is the cause of the expenses of production. That is, men 
 think it worth while to expend money in producing things be- 
 cause they think that the products will have value enough to 
 recompense them for the expenses of production. 
 
 Many of the economists who have written in the past about 
 the subject of value took the facts of demand for granted, and 
 devoted most of their treatment of the subject to an examina- 
 tion of the relation between value and the expenses of produc- 
 tion. This was in part an expression of a general tendency to 
 regard the production of wealth as something to be desired for 
 its own sake; the fact that the satisfaction of human wants is
 
 VALUE AND PRICE 185 
 
 the real goal of most economic efforts being underemphasized. 
 In more recent years economic writers have developed the analy- 
 sis of human wants; the fact that utility in the economic sense 
 is not utility in general, but the utility of a particular unit of a 
 commodity, being the most significant point in this new analysis. 
 Some writers have even gone so far as to take the facts of supply 
 for granted, and to assume that value is explained when mar- 
 ginal utility is described. Marginal utility is, as we have seen, 
 the equivalent of subjective value the importance an indi- 
 vidual attaches to the possession of a particular unit of a com- 
 modity. To say that the marginal utility of an object determines 
 its exchange value is, however, to argue in a circle, for the mar- 
 ginal utility of a commodity to me depends on the intensity of 
 my wants and the extent to which they are satisfied. But the 
 extent to which our wants are satisfied depends very largely upon 
 the difficulty or expense of acquiring the things that satisfy them. 
 In this sense value determines marginal utility. The concept 
 of marginal utility does, however, aid us in understanding the 
 causes of exchange value, because it forms a bridge by which 
 we can pass from the definite money units in which exchange 
 values are measured to the indefinite, subjective units of satis- 
 faction in which we measure the utility of goods. 
 
 As a determining cause of value, utility has a logical priority 
 over scarcity, in the sense that demand is usually the cause of 
 supply. Yet in the analysis of the actual valuation process we 
 have to recognize that utility and scarcity, demand and supply, 
 are forces operating simultaneously, neither of which can be 
 neglected without obscuring the fundamental facts of the market. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Is there any relation between the price of a lead pencil and the expense 
 of producing it ? 
 
 2. What elements of a farmer's expenses are "constant"? What are 
 " variable" ? 
 
 3. What different possible standards of just price can you suggest ? 
 
 4. Draw diagrams illustrating the fixing of normal value under different 
 conditions of long-period supply, the conditions of demand being assumed to 
 be constant.
 
 l86 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 5. What different possible meanings can be attached to the expression 
 ''natural value" ? 
 
 6. Discuss the following statement : 
 
 "The fact is that labor once spent has no influence on the future value of any 
 article ; it is lost and gone forever. In commerce bygones are forever by- 
 gones ; and we are always starting clear at each moment, judging the value 
 of things with a view to future utility." Jevons, Theory of Political Econ- 
 omy, p. 164. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 FLUX, A. W. Economic Principles, Chaps. IV and V. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 4th ed., Book V, Chaps. Ill, 
 
 IV, V, VI, VII, XI, XII. Or [abridged], Economics of Industry, 3d 
 
 ed., Book V, Chaps. III-VIII. 
 
 MILL, J. S. Principles of Political Economy, Book III, Chaps. Ill and IV. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Principles of Economics, Chaps. XVI, XVII. 
 WIESER, E. VON. Natural Value, Book V, Chaps. I-VI.
 
 CHAPTER XIII 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 The Idea of Monopoly. One of the economic terms most fre- 
 quently used nowadays is monopoly, and at the same time it 
 is one of those terms which are peculiarly vague and ill-defined 
 in popular discussion. Even in law and economics, contradictory 
 meanings have been attached to the term, although recently there 
 has been a marked clarification of thought both on the part of 
 economists and jurists. This has been a natural result of the 
 discussion of the subject; and this discussion in turn has been a 
 necessary outcome of an economic situation in which monopoly 
 has played and is still playing a large r61e. While there has been 
 confusion of thought with respect to monopoly, all have agreed that 
 something to be called monopoly has existed, and that it has been 
 the cause of perplexing scientific and practical problems. 
 
 In economics, as in life, categories shade off into each other, and 
 at the boundaries discrimination is difficult. It is best, therefore, 
 to find highly developed, plainly marked types to furnish us the 
 subject-matter for definition and to compare one type with another. 
 This is an especially desirable mode of procedure in the present 
 case, because the term " monopoly " at once suggests the term " com- 
 petition," with which it is inevitably contrasted. When monopoly 
 exists, competition is thought of as absent. A state of full and 
 free competition, on the other hand, is incompatible with mo- 
 nopoly. 
 
 Competition means a market with rival sellers and buyers, 
 and prices determined, on the one hand, by efforts of sellers, 
 acting independently of one another, to dispose of commodities 
 and services, and on the other hand, by efforts of purchasers, 
 acting independently of one another, to secure commodities and 
 services. Competition means goods and services freely produced; 
 
 187
 
 1 88 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 in other words, without control by combination. We have seen 
 the forces that under competition limit producers and purchasers, 
 and thus determine value. 
 
 Monopoly, as the term contrasted with competition, means com- 
 bination and unified action, signifying restraint on the free offering 
 of commodities and services by rival sellers and on the free pur- 
 chase of these commodities and services by rivals who desire to 
 secure them. The word " monopoly " itself means a condition in 
 which there is a single seller and by extension a single purchaser, 
 and signifies unity in management of some kind of business in 
 some essential particular. 
 
 The particular in which unity is secured in the case of monopoly 
 may be in production, it may be in sales, it may be in purchases; 
 or it may be in any two or all three of these particulars. This 
 use of the term " monopoly " gives us a clear scientific concept which 
 is workable; and on its basis we may then formulate this definition 
 of monopoly: Monopoly means that substantial unity of action 
 on the part of one or more persons engaged in some kind of business 
 which gives exclusive control, more particularly, although not solely, 
 with respect to price. 
 
 A few points in our definition require comment. Price is 
 essential, and must be regarded as the fundamental test of monop- 
 oly, even if it is obvious that price formation and price control 
 do not exhaust monopoly, since its import reaches beyond price. 
 The other things than price control which monopoly carries with 
 it flow from such control and are not secure without it. A cer- 
 tain unity of action may be obtained without the establishment of 
 monopoly, since it does not give rise to monopoly until the power 
 to control price is secured. 
 
 It is possible that monopoly may not prevent price from falling 
 below cost, and such a condition of price is quite compatible with 
 the definition given. The advantage of unified action may be 
 that loss is diminished. Sometimes a monopoly will give, perhaps, 
 simply normal returns; sometimes there is loss, as in the case of 
 an unprofitable copyrighted book; sometimes it might happen 
 that the monopoly price would be exactly the same as the com- 
 petitive price; sometimes it may go, and generally will go, above
 
 MONOPOLY 189 
 
 the competitive price, 1 although there might be other gains than 
 those resulting from higher price. 
 
 The precise definition given here of monopoly appears in the 
 main to be in accordance with the best English usage, and also to 
 be in harmony with the meaning given to the corresponding word 
 in other modern languages by those who use these languages 
 with discrimination. If we search our dictionaries for the 
 meanings of monopoly, it will be seen that there runs through them 
 all the notion of exclusiveness or unity as the dominating thought, 
 as the essential thing for which the mind is more or less success- 
 fully struggling and the thought about which other things are 
 grouped. 
 
 When we search our law books and judicial utterances on the 
 subject of monopoly, unsatisfactory as they have been to all in- 
 terests involved and contradictory to one another in their 
 interpretations in various particulars, we find, nevertheless, a 
 sound tendency to emphasize unified control of business as an 
 essential characteristic of monopoly. Lord Coke, in the seven- 
 teenth century, laid emphasis upon the exclusive nature of mo- 
 nopoly, when he said that it consisted of power granted "to any 
 person or persons, bodies politic or corporate, for the sole buying, 
 selling, making, working, or using of anything, whereby any per- 
 son or persons, bodies politic or corporate, are sought to be re- 
 strained of any freedom or liberty that they had before, or hindered 
 in their lawful trade." 7 Blackstone, in his Commentaries on the 
 Laws of England, gave almost precisely the same definition in 
 the following century. Recent American decisions lay emphasis 
 on exclusiveness as a test of monopoly. 
 
 The Idea of Monopoly and Industrial Evolution. But the 
 meanings of economic categories change with industrial evolution. 
 Even such terms as freedom and liberty have to be newly inter- 
 preted with every new stage and even with every marked phase in 
 a stage of economic life. Naturally monopoly has acquired a new 
 significance, requiring new interpretation, which even courts are 
 
 1 This point is discussed later in the present chapter, vide p. 206. 
 
 2 Coke, 3 Institutes, 181. Quoted by C. F. Beach, Sr., in his Monopolies and 
 Industrial Trusts, 5.
 
 1 90 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 gradually learning to give. The earlier legal definitions made 
 monopoly proceed from an express grant of public authority. 
 Lord Coke says: " A monopoly is an institution or allowance by 
 the king, by his grant, commission, or otherwise ;" and Black- 
 stone uses similar language in denning monopoly " as a license or 
 privilege allowed by the king." 
 
 Historically, this source of monopoly power is of paramount 
 importance. From early times, English sovereigns granted mo- 
 nopolies either for public or private reasons, and they became a 
 grievous burden. Queen Elizabeth, in particular, sinned in this 
 respect, regarding the right to grant monopolies as " one of the 
 fairest flowers" in her prerogative, and it was not long before 
 the citizen found himself restrained and shut in on every side by 
 a privileged class of monopolists. 1 
 
 Our forefathers were so deeply impressed with the evils which 
 they had suffered at the hands of the monopolists in old England 
 that in the Bills of Rights and elsewhere in the early constitutions 
 of our commonwealths they frequently inserted severe denun- 
 ciations of monopolies, and prohibited them unqualifiedly; and 
 these declarations and prohibitions still last in several states. 
 Two illustrations will suffice. We read the following utterance in 
 Article 39 of the Declaration of Rights which forms part of the 
 constitution of Maryland : " Monopolies are odious, contrary to 
 the spirit of a free government and the principles of commerce, 
 and ought not to be suffered." And the people of Texas still 
 cherish Section 26 of Article I of their constitution, which among 
 other things declares that " monopolies are contrary to the genius 
 of a free government, and shall never be allowed." 
 
 While the spirit of monopoly is as old as man, there was until 
 this century comparatively little opportunity for monopoly on 
 any large scale save as it proceeded from express grants of public 
 authority. These grants were sometimes made for public purposes, 
 and sometimes they proceeded from mere abuse of monarchical 
 power, and were given to favorites of royalty. We cannot now 
 stop to discuss their merits and demerits, but call attention to the 
 
 1 For a scholarly treatment of Elizabethan monopolies, see English Patents 
 of Monopoly, by W. H. Price.
 
 MONOPOLY ! 9I 
 
 fact that they became odious, and were prohibited both in England 
 and in this country, exception being made of patents, copyrights, 
 and trade-marks. At the present time, however, monopolies pro- 
 ceed from the nature of industrial society, and are of far greater 
 significance in our economic and political life than ever before. 
 The really serious monopolies of our day are far more subtle, 
 and have for the most part grown up outside of the law, and even 
 in spite of the law. 
 
 And this has at last received full recognition in an utterance of 
 the Supreme Court of the United States in which the idea of mo- 
 nopoly, as stated in our definition, is reproduced; l and thus, for- 
 tunately, law and economics are brought into harmony, as they 
 always should be. 
 
 Complete and Partial Monopolies. We have taken a perfect 
 type of monopoly to furnish us with our definition; but there are 
 imperfect types, or incomplete monopolies, as well as complete 
 monopolies. We have a partial monopoly where there is a unified 
 control over a considerable portion of the industrial field, but not 
 over a sufficient portion to give complete domination of the whole 
 field. It can easily be understood that if 90 per cent of a 
 given business, but no smaller percentage, would afford control 
 over the whole business, 80 per cent, while it would not be 
 sufficient for domination, might carry with it an advantage to 
 the person or persons enjoying unified control over the 80 per 
 cent, yielding an excess above competitive returns which we 
 may properly designate as one sort of surplus value. Busi- 
 nesses must often be in this position, and a monopoly may 
 be obliged to go through several stages of partial monopoly be- 
 fore it reaches a position where it can exercise unified control 
 over the entire business. After all, it is a question of degree of 
 control; and nearly, if not quite all, economic distinctions are 
 matters of degree. 
 
 But we must distinguish sharply between a condition of mo- 
 nopoly and other conditions, if we are to think clearly and ac- 
 curately. One thing which does not yield monopoly is mere limi- 
 tation of supply, and it is strange that even an economist of the 
 McKenna, J., in National Cotton Oil Co. v. Texas, 197 U. S. 139.
 
 192 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ability of John Stuart Mill should have found the essential feature 
 of monopoly in this limitation ; for this at once makes monopoly 
 cover the entire field of economic activity, inasmuch as economic 
 activity is for the acquisition of valuable things, and things lack 
 value whenever their supply is adequate for the satisfaction of 
 all wants. It is only things limited in proportion to human desires 
 that have value. 
 
 Nor may we say that a valuable thing is monopolized because 
 its supply is limited and also graded in quality. Land exists in 
 quantities to which physical nature has assigned limits, and the 
 supply of land exists in grades varying in fertility and desirability 
 of situation, and as a consequence of this gradation we have the 
 rent of land. Land is not, however, a monopoly, and it is mis- 
 leading to speak of it as a natural monopoly. Nowhere do we 
 find monopoly either in the ownership or in the cultivation of 
 land, but everywhere competition competition among unequals, 
 to be sure, but still competition. 
 
 Land rent is a differential gain, a gain due to the superiority of 
 the land owned by rent receivers over that cultivated by those 
 who are making use of land which affords nothing beyond returns 
 to labor and to capital. Now we must distinguish between the 
 broad concept of differential gains enjoyed by those in competi- 
 tive pursuits, and the monopolistic gains which are based on the 
 absence of competition. 
 
 Just as sharply must we distinguish between competitive busi- 
 nesses of large magnitude and monopolies. Department stores 
 in no city in the world enjoy monopolies, but are subjected to the 
 steady, permanent pressure of competition. There are those who 
 call every business operating on a vast scale monopoly, and would 
 put in the same economic category a gasworks without a compet- 
 itor and a huge retail dry-goods establishment with rivals at every 
 hand, ready to seize every opportunity for an advantage over it, 
 and certain to ruin it if its managers relax their intense activity 
 and watchfulness. 
 
 Classification and Causes of Monopolies. As our first step in 
 the treatment is the formulation of the idea of monopoly, our 
 second must be the classification of monopolies with an examina-
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 193 
 
 tion of their causes. Comparatively little can be said about mo- 
 nopolies that is applicable to all monopolistic businesses. Here, 
 as everywhere else in economics, we need analysis. 
 
 Many classifications of monopolies have been given, but we must 
 here confine ourselves to the three which seem of the greatest 
 importance to the general student. 
 
 First Classification 
 
 A. Public Monopolies. 
 
 B. Private Monopolies. 1 
 
 C. Quasi-public Monopolies. 
 
 Public Monopolies are those businesses which are owned and 
 operated by some political unit, and this political unit is the direct 
 and immediate beneficiary ; in other words, to this political unit in 
 the first place flow all the benefits of monopoly. A Private Mo- 
 nopoly, on the other hand, is a monopoly owned and operated by a 
 private person ; it may be a natural person, that is, a human 
 being, or some association of natural persons, as a partner- 
 ship, or it may be a private corporation. In this case the first and 
 immediate beneficiary of the benefits of the property and business 
 is the private person, although large benefits may flow to the 
 general public. 
 
 It is believed that this great fundamental distinction between 
 public and private monopolies is essential both to clear thinking 
 and to sound public policy. Whoever undertakes to tell us what 
 is true about monopolies, and what is wise for society to do with 
 respect to monopolies, must make it plain whether he is talking 
 about public monopolies or whether he is discussing private mo- 
 nopolies. We may also have an intermediate class designated as 
 Quasi-public Monopolies. An illustration is afforded by state- 
 owned railways operated by private corporations; although prac- 
 tically, in the United States, these differ in their management 
 little from the privately owned railways. 
 
 1 In our classifications the coordinate classes will be indicated by the same 
 letters or marks. The capital letters will indicate the chief classes; the Roman 
 numerals, classes subordinate to them; and the Arabic, classes subordinate to 
 those indicated by Roman numerals, and so on. 
 O
 
 194 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Second Classification. The second classification of monopolies 
 is made with reference to the source of monopoly power, and is 
 based upon a different principle of classification, so that this second 
 classification will cut across the first. We have again two main 
 classes, and these are: A. Social Monopolies; B. Natural Mo- 
 nopolies. These are further classified as follows : 
 
 A . Social Monopolies. 
 
 I. General welfare monopolies. 
 
 1. Patents. 
 
 2. Copyrights. 
 
 3. Trade-marks. 
 
 4. Public consumption monopolies. 
 
 5. Fiscal monopolies. 
 
 II. Special privilege monopolies. 
 
 1. Those based on public favoritism. 
 
 2. Those based on private favoritism. 
 
 B. Natural Monopolies. 
 
 I. Those arising from limitation of supply of raw ma- 
 terial. 
 II. Those arising from peculiar properties inherent in 
 
 the business. 
 III. Those arising from secrecy. 
 
 Social Monopolies. Businesses are social monopolies when they 
 are made monopolies not by their own inherent properties, but either 
 by legislative ~ enactment or by forming so close a connection with 
 great natural monopolies that they partake of the nature of the latter. 
 
 As already stated, in old times kings and queens frequently 
 granted exclusive business privileges to favored persons, and per- 
 mitted no one except those named to engage in such undertakings. 
 Such monopolies, however, became so odious that sovereigns were 
 compelled to cease granting them. Governments still create 
 exclusive privileges by patent and copyright laws, but they do so 
 in behalf of the general public. Authors and inventors are given 
 exclusive rights over their productions for a limited period. These 
 monopolies have justified themselves through the stimulus which 
 they have given to invention and authorship.
 
 MONOPOLY I95 
 
 The trade-mark is a legal monopoly similar to the patent and the 
 copyright. In connection with lavish advertising, trade-marks 
 in recent days have been made the basis of enormous profits. 1 
 
 Public consumption monopolies and fiscal monopolies call for 
 a word of special comment. They are to be distinguished the one 
 from the other only by the object which the government has in 
 view in establishing them. If the government manages for itself 
 or grants to another a monopoly of the liquor traffic with the object 
 of regulating the consumption, the monopoly is a public consump- 
 tion monopoly. If, on the other hand, the chief object is not 
 regulation, but income, the monopoly is a fiscal one. Often the 
 two objects are so blended that it is difficult or impossible to say 
 to which class the resulting monopoly belongs. 
 
 Our classification names two kinds of special privilege monopo- 
 lies. Those monopolies which are due to special tariff advantages 
 or to other legislation are rightly said to be based on public favorit- 
 ism. The other class of special privilege monopolies consists of 
 those which grow up through special favors granted by other 
 monopolies, especially natural monopolies, such as railways. 
 
 Natural Monopolies. Natural monopolies are those which 
 depend for their existence on natural forces as distinguished from 
 social arrangements. They grow up independently of man's will 
 and desire, and sometimes even in direct opposition to it. The 
 words which we have used in our classification will sufficiently 
 explain the different sources from which they arise. By far the 
 most important of all monopolies are natural monopolies of the 
 second class, chief among which are the following: wagon roads 
 
 1 The full treatment of trade-marks involves theoretical points which would 
 necessitate a discussion too lengthy for the present treatise. They are used largely 
 in competitive businesses, and help to establish what is termed good-will. They 
 are an aid to the shrewd and capable in the general effort to escape what may be 
 designated as the "dead level" of competition. They are a monopoly not in the 
 sense of giving exclusive control of one sort of business, but in the strictly legal 
 sense that no one else may use them. A clever device, coupled with excellence and 
 advertising, may have very high value. The purchaser of oysters, for example, 
 may feel that when he buys oysters of a particular "brand" (trade-mark), he is 
 getting oysters, plus something else ; or, in other words, not merely oysters such 
 as others sell, but a peculiar excellence which can nowhere else surely be had. 
 It is merely this "plus something else" that is a monopoly. Great importance is 
 attached thus to "establishing a brand."
 
 196 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 and streets, canals, docks, bridges and ferries, waterways, harbors, 
 lighthouses, railways, telegraphs, telephones, the post office, 
 electric lighting, waterworks, gas works, street railways of all 
 kinds. Whenever there is a decided increment in gain resulting 
 from combination, -we have a tendency to monopoly -which will over- 
 come all obstacles. This increment of gain, which is the cause of 
 monopoly, is always present in businesses that occupy peculiarly 
 favorable spots or lines of land, and that furnish services or com- 
 modities which must be used in connection with the plant. This 
 may be said to be the law of natural monopolies. 
 
 Many economists believe that combination and production on the largest 
 possible scale give a decided increment in gain, and thus produce monopolies 
 to be designated as "capitalistic monopolies." The question really turns 
 upon the degree of growth of a business unit which adds to the rate of gain ; 
 and the position is taken in this book that in most kinds of business the point 
 of maximum efficiency is reached long before the point of monopoly is reached. 
 
 One or two very cogent reasons may, however, be stated. An exhaustive 
 study of the cases cited in support of the alleged tendency to monopoly in- 
 herent in large capital has failed to reveal a single one in which the monopoly 
 did not enjoy one or many of those monopoly advantages which we have al- 
 ready mentioned and explained. Moreover, many cases in which the pos- 
 session of large capital seemed on the surface to be a dominating influence, 
 have been cases in which the monopoly was so short-lived as to furnish little 
 support to the argument of those who cited them. After all, whatever may be 
 the advantage conferred by large capital, we must remember that capital is 
 so plentiful that one gigantic plant can always find a rival whenever a slight 
 margin of profit invites its establishment. 
 
 Our conclusion, then, maybe stated as follows: There is a great 
 and growing field of industry in which competition is not natural 
 or permanently possible, for reasons explained in the text; there 
 is another field within which monopoly does not and cannot exist, 
 and within which social monopoly is unlikely to arise. 
 
 Third Classification 
 A. Local Monopolies 
 
 These are monopolies extending over a relatively small area. 
 The gas supply of any city is an illustration. There are various 
 monopolies which are confined to a single locality. Then there
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 I 97 
 
 are temporary local monopolies which, under peculiar exigencies, 
 may arise. Two young men in Chicago a few winters ago 
 cornered the market on eggs, and made fifteen thousand dol- 
 lars out of the operation. The weather was so cold that eggs 
 could not be shipped to the city, and for a few days these 
 speculators had a monopoly. 
 
 B. National Monopolies 
 C. International or Universal Monopolies 
 
 There have been various attempts to secure universal monopoly, 
 of which the copper monopoly of 1889 affords an illustration. 
 
 These are more or less arbitrary divisions, because a protective 
 tariff may enable a monopoly to exist in one country when the 
 same article or service is not monopolized in another country. 
 There are attempts to establish monopolies beyond the nation, 
 but how large will be the number of cases in which success will 
 be achieved, remains to be seen. There is no doubt that the oil 
 companies of the United States and Russia are endeavoring to 
 establish an international and even a world monopoly. 
 
 The area of monopoly is a topic that in an extended treatise would 
 require an elaborate treatment, for it has a significance which has 
 as yet not been anywhere adequately presented. We can narrow 
 down the area of monopoly until nearly every producer of goods 
 or seller of services has a monopoly. A may be the only seller 
 of shoes on a particular street of his city or in a particular block 
 or building on his street. No one is especially disturbed or in- 
 convenienced by a monopoly of so limited an area. In general, 
 it may be said that, 
 
 The larger the area, other things being equal, the more significant 
 is the monopoly. 
 
 Monopoly Price. Price in general depends upon marginal 
 utility, and that depends upon the intensity of desire and upon 
 the difficulty or ease of obtaining goods or services for the satis- 
 faction of desire. If payment is made in money or in money in- 
 struments, price depends on the relative abundance of the supply
 
 198 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of money and its instruments. 1 We see that price, then, depends 
 upon limitation of supply in all cases, because it is the limitation 
 of supply which gives us the utility of a particular concrete good, or 
 our marginal utility. As the supply increases, the desires satisfied 
 are of a lower and lower order until the point of satiety is reached, 
 where all desires are satisfied and where value entirely disappears. 
 
 We now reach the chief peculiarity of monopoly price, which is 
 found in the power of the monopolist over supply. The very con- 
 cept of a unified control over business means power to control 
 and limit supply. Supply is limited by the monopolist at that 
 point where he gets the greatest returns, and if he receives surplus 
 returns, they are due to the fact that he is in a position to compel 
 men to forego satisfaction. 
 
 Under competition in the case of freely reproducible goods, 
 supply is limited by cost of production. If the cost of production 
 were nothing, there would be no limit to supply until all wants 
 were satisfied. Competition in its very nature means that supply 
 is not within the control of a single producer; and this fact gives 
 us the protection that competition affords to society; and it is 
 on this account that the courts regard competition as one of the 
 main pillars of our present social order. 
 
 Now as the supply is not determined as under competition by 
 the cost of production, it is determined by the desire of the mo- 
 nopolist to secure the maximum of revenue possible in the existing 
 state of demand. In other words, the monopolist, freed from com- 
 petition, and governed only by demand, is able to adjust supply to 
 demand in such a way that the price will stand at the point of 
 highest net return. In determining what price shall be fixed and 
 what quantity supplied, in other words, what is the point of 
 highest net returns, the monopolist consciously or unconsciously 
 proceeds according to the following principles : 
 
 i. He realizes that, other things being equal, every increase of 
 his monopolized product will result in lowering its price, while 
 every decrease in the supply will result in a higher price. 
 
 1 And abundance of money will depend upon marginal cost of production of 
 the precious metals. This subject is treated elsewhere, as also the general subject 
 of price, which is here presented only in abbreviated form for present purposes.
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 199 
 
 2. Of the expenses of production there are some that in a well- 
 organized business vary roughly in proportion to variation in the 
 supply. It will frequently happen that if the product is doubled, 
 the cost of raw material will be about doubled. Such expenses 
 may be called variable expenses. 
 
 3. Other expenses, within the limits of maximum efficiency, 
 remain more nearly the same, no matter what may be the amount 
 of the product. These, called the fixed or constant expenses, 
 include the cost of plant, salary of superintendent, interest on 
 bonds, etc. 
 
 It follows from the above principles that the monopolist, in a 
 case of this kind, since he is seeking the maximum net revenue 
 from his business, will pay little attention to fixed charges in 
 establishing the price of the product, but will consider chiefly 
 the variable expenses in connection with the probable demand 
 for his goods at various points. 1 
 
 An Illustration. We may illustrate by an example the opera- 
 tion of these principles. The following table shows in parallel 
 columns the number of sales of a monopolized good at different 
 prices; the total resultant earnings; the variable expenses; the 
 fixed expenses; the total expenses; and finally, the net revenue or 
 monopoly profit : 
 
 
 S 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 O 
 
 H 
 fa S3 
 
 t 
 
 M 
 
 sl| 
 
 SB 
 
 2 W fc 
 
 < 15 
 
 s a 
 
 < 1 
 
 H < S 
 
 s 
 g s 
 
 ^ u 
 
 ^ S 
 
 ^ s 
 
 H S 
 
 z. 
 
 H 
 
 H 
 
 8 
 
 w 
 
 9 
 
 OS 0* ^ 
 
 o S 
 
 h 
 
 5 " 
 
 M 
 
 P-t w 
 
 
 H < 
 
 < x g 
 
 H < x 
 
 fa X 
 
 H x 
 
 
 R 
 
 P 
 
 W 
 
 > w 
 
 > W 
 
 H 
 
 M 
 
 & 
 
 
 S5 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 !s 
 
 $.10 
 
 600,000 
 
 $ 60,000 
 
 $.03 
 
 $ 18,000 
 
 $50,000 
 
 $ 68,000 
 
 -SS.cco 
 
 .09 
 
 800,000 
 
 72,000 
 
 03 
 
 24,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 74,000 
 
 2,OOO 
 
 .08 
 
 1,200,000 
 
 96,000 
 
 3 
 
 36,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 86,000 
 
 + 10,000 
 
 .07 
 
 1,800,000 
 
 126,000 
 
 .O^ 
 
 54,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 104,000 
 
 + 22,000 
 
 .06 
 
 2,500,000 
 
 150,000 
 
 .O "? 
 
 75,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 125,000 
 
 + 25,000 
 
 5 
 
 3,500,000 
 
 175,000 
 
 3 
 
 105,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 155,000 
 
 + 20,000 
 
 .04 
 
 5,500,000 
 
 22O,OCO 
 
 03 
 
 165,000 
 
 50,000 
 
 215,000 
 
 + 5,000 
 
 1 This subject would require further treatment in a larger work, but the limit 
 of space and proper proportions compel us here to confine ourselves to the broad 
 general statement.
 
 200 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Study of the table will show why, in the case assumed here, the 
 monopoly price will stand at six cents. Competition, if it were 
 present, would keep on increasing the supply as long as normal 
 profit could be obtained. In our illustration the lowest price at 
 which production could be carried on so as just to secure a profit 
 above the expenses of production would be four cents; and four 
 cents would therefore be the competitive price, or the price deter- 
 mined by the balancing of marginal utility against marginal cost 
 of production. But since the monopolist has such control over 
 the production that he can control the supply, he will cut off pro- 
 duction at 2,500,000 units, at which point demand will fix a price 
 of six cents, and will give the largest net return, viz. $25,000. 
 
 But the case here assumed is one that is far simpler than the cases frequently 
 presented by real life. We should have to take many different illustrations 
 even to approximate the rich complexity of economic life. We have, for 
 example, assumed constant fixed charges, and such an assumption is one that 
 is frequently helpful, because it often corresponds to actuality. But "fixed 
 charges," so called, are, from the long-time point of view, variable. The 
 constant charges of a street-railway system imply a street-railway system at a 
 particular time and place and a street-railway system of a particular kind, 
 e.g. one with single track and switches. If a street-railway system is enlarged 
 so as to necessitate "double-tracking" and a new power plant, we will have 
 new fixed charges. But anything like an exhaustive discussion of these 
 points requires so much space as to be suitable only for special treatises. 1 
 
 The Effect of a Tax. Our numerical illustration may be made to convey 
 a lesson regarding the influence of taxation upon monopolies and monopoly 
 price. Fixed expenses have no influence in determining the price. If, 
 therefore, a fixed tax, say of $5000 a year, were to be laid upon this monopoly, 
 it would not result in an increase of price. A study of the table will show that 
 with such a tax the net revenue at price .08 would be $5000; at price. 07, 
 $17,000; at price .06, $20,000; at price .05, $15,000; at price .04, nothing. 
 Thus price .06 will still be the point of maximum net revenue, and hence the 
 monopoly price. On the other hand, a variable tax, for instance, a tax of one 
 cent per unit, would result in this case in raising the monopoly price. In 
 our illustration, such a tax would make the net revenue at the price .08, 
 
 $2000; at the price .07, $4000; at the price .06, nothing; at the price .05, 
 
 $15,000. Thus, though the monopoly would find its profits greatly curtailed 
 by such a tax, consumers would be compelled to pay one cent more per unit 
 for the monopoly product. The possible advantage which society might 
 
 1 See references to literature at the close of the chapter. See also the treatment 
 of Constant and Variable Expenses in Chapter XII on Value and Price.
 
 MONOPOLY 201 
 
 draw from the tax would therefore be wholly or in part offset by the increased 
 cost of the commodity. Such a raising of the price will not take place, however, 
 if the demand at the higher price is not sufficient to make as great a net 
 revenue as at the lower price. We may conclude, therefore, that fixed taxes, 
 or taxes on the net revenue of a monopoly, cannot be shifted wholly or in part 
 by a change in price ; while taxes laid in proportion to the amount of business, 
 since they contribute an addition to the variable expenses, may be wholly or in 
 part shifted by a change in price. 
 
 A Law of Monopoly Price. It is sometimes said that the price 
 of a monopolized good depends solely upon the will of the monop- 
 olist. In the strict sense of the phrase this is not true. As our 
 explanation has shown, the monopolist is forced by economic mo- 
 tives to establish such a price as will give the maximum net reve- 
 nue. There are certain conditions on the side of demand which 
 therefore have a decisive influence in determining monopoly price. 
 We may group the most important of these in a general statement 
 which may properly be called the law of monopoly price: The greater 
 the intensity of customary use of the monopolized commodity or 
 service, the higher the general average of economic well-being, and 
 the more readily wealth is generally expended, the higher will be 
 the monopoly price which will yield the largest net returns. 
 
 The phrase, intensity of customary use, may require explanation. 
 It signifies simply the strength of custom with respect to the use 
 of a monopolized article. If the people of France, for example, 
 are accustomed to use large quantities of tobacco, there a gov- 
 ernment monopoly, and if they cling with a high degree of in- 
 tensity to this custom, it will obviously be possible profitably to 
 raise the price a great deal above competitive price; whereas, if 
 the custom is one that is relatively weak, that is, weak as com- 
 pared with the force to which they cling to their customary con- 
 sumption of other articles, a very high price will so diminish 
 consumption as to lessen net profits. 
 
 Thus monopoly, without any effort of its own, shares in the in- 
 creasing wealth of a country, and absorbs a considerable part of 
 it. It is, for example, among other influences, the larger wealth 
 and the greater willingness to spend freely that makes monopoly 
 more profitable in the United States than in Germany or other 
 European countries. The search for other illustrations of the
 
 202 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 law should prove an interesting and valuable exercise for the 
 student. 
 
 Class Price. Thus far we have assumed that the monopolist 
 charges one uniform price and sets the price at the point which 
 yields him the largest net returns. But it is obvious that his gains 
 will be increased if he is able to vary his price. His gains would 
 be highest if he could charge each individual that price which would 
 yield the largest net returns, taking into account the number of 
 sales and profits on each. A rich man and a free spender might 
 pay double the current rates for gas or electric light without 
 diminishing his consumption in the least. But in the case of any 
 large modern business it is obviously impracticable to fix a price 
 for each individual, even were there no legal difficulties in the way, 
 as there are in the case of the great monopolistic businesses such 
 as gas and electric lighting, railway transportation, etc. The 
 next best thing for the monopolist is to divide his public into classes, 
 and to charge to each class that price which will yield the largest 
 net returns. In the table already given, we found that six cents was 
 the monopoly price on the hypothesis of one uniform price, but 
 obviously, if the eight-cent and seven-cent prices could be secured, 
 and six cents reserved as a price for sales that could not be made 
 at eight or seven cents, the profits would be still higher. This 
 gives rise to what, in its broad, general terms, we call class price. 
 The monopolist seeks in every possible way to divide his community 
 into classes and to secure from each the highest possible price. 
 We observe a remarkable development of class price in the case 
 of our railways; and, unless legal obstacles are interposed, this 
 development will doubtless go still farther. We have special 
 trains with an extra charge. We have privately owned railway 
 coaches; our drawing-rooms and single seats in "parlor cars"; 
 our ordinary first-class tickets ; and our second-class tickets, the 
 purchasers of which frequently ride in the " day coach " with 
 the first-class passengers. Then we have single tickets, fifty-trip 
 family tickets, monthly commutation tickets, etc., with enormous 
 variations in price. We may go farther and say that the whole 
 American railway rate system of " charging what the traffic will 
 bear " is a consummate example of monopoly prices.
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 203 
 
 Nor need it be supposed that in all its ramifications class price 
 is a bad thing. It is, when ignorance and need are exploited by 
 a special high price ; frequently it works well when an attempt 
 is made to reach a class of limited means with a very low price, 
 as in the case of early and late workingmen's trains, etc. 
 
 Monopoly price will vary with use also ; and this is one special 
 subhead under class price, and may be designated as use price. 
 The typical instance is that of two prices frequently charged for 
 gas : a higher when it is used for illuminating purposes ; a lower 
 when it is used for fuel. 
 
 Monopoly price necessarily varies from country to country, 
 from place to place, and from time to time. This follows neces- 
 sarily from our law of monopoly price, and is a matter of familiar 
 observation. The monopoly price yielding the highest net returns 
 is lower among the careful, prudent Germans with relatively small 
 incomes than it is among the free-spending Americans with rela- 
 tively large incomes often easily earned. 
 
 A difficulty suggests itself at this point, and this is found in the 
 departure from uniformity of price of non-monopolized articles and 
 services. We have to consider the question: Are the apparent 
 class prices in competitive businesses class prices in the true sense 
 of the term ? If so, wherein does the competitive class price differ 
 from the monopolistic class price? To answer this question we 
 must first of all consider the distinction between what we may 
 term " commodity competition " and " business unit competition." 
 
 When we speak about commodity competition, we have refer- 
 ence to that competition with respect to a commodity which gives 
 uniform price, if competition works perfectly. We think of the 
 great staples like wheat and wool, those staples which have a 
 world market. But the competition between retail business men 
 is a competition of a different sort. It is the competition of one 
 business unit as such with another business unit as such. It is 
 a kind of competition that exists between the grocers in the same 
 city, or mammoth department stores in New York and Chicago. 
 It is competition which is frequently very sharp ; but even when it 
 is the sharpest, it does not mean in retail trade real commodity 
 competition. It does not mean that the prices of all goods sold
 
 204 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 are the same, but it means this: where we have sharp competition 
 the gains are in proportion to expenditure of economic energy, 
 using that term " economic energy " as a composite term imply- 
 ing a certain output of economic force, whether this takes the form 
 of labor or capital or business management. 
 
 Each one of the business units will make a specialty of some 
 one line of commodities upon certain days. Special prices will 
 be offered ; but that means something very different from the class 
 price which we have considered in our discussion of monopoly. 
 Every one will agree that that is the case. The consumer considers 
 very generally the prices charged as a whole. He knows very well 
 when he goes to one retail establishment that for a certain par- 
 ticular article he may be paying a little bit more than he would 
 pay in some other store ; but the retail purchaser as a general rule 
 does not consider each individual price, but he considers all the 
 prices that he pays. It is intolerable for the consumer to go 
 about a town searching for the lowest price of every little com- 
 modity, to buy a paper of pins at one place because it is a little 
 cheaper than at any other place, to buy a pound of butter at one 
 place, a pound of sugar at another. People do not ordinarily 
 do that. 
 
 Now each retailer looks upon his business as a unit. He tries 
 to derive from the business as a whole the greatest profit. Each 
 one is putting his capacity into the business. One says, " I can 
 do better if I sell this article at cost, or if I sell that article some- 
 what below cost." It was not very long ago that' a large depart- 
 ment store in New York City sold the popular magazines at less 
 than was paid for them. That was not a class price in any sense 
 of the term. That was a certain expenditure for advertising 
 purposes. 
 
 To some extent people do go about and try to get all the special 
 prices in each particular establishment, but that is not done usu- 
 ally, so far as purchases as a whole are concerned. On the other 
 hand, there is a limitation very often in the arrangement that a 
 store will sell only so much one pair of gloves or so many yards 
 of silk at a special price to one customer. But we are dealing 
 here with a different sort of phenomenon from class price.
 
 MONOPOLY 205 
 
 In wholesale business there is an attempt to unite the business 
 unit competition and the commodity competition. Here the pur- 
 chases are very much larger, and a person does not hesitate, to 
 a certain extent, to go from one wholesaler to another wholesaler 
 to make a particular purchase of some articles. Many persons 
 would be a little bit ashamed to divide their groceries among a 
 half-dozen grocers so as to get at each place the articles selling at 
 a special price. When we have a unity of these two sorts of com- 
 petition, then we have what we may call perfect competition, 
 where we have a competition between the business units which 
 includes a commodity competition, so that all articles are selling 
 at the same price and each dealer has net returns in proportion 
 to what he puts in of economic energy. 
 
 It is in the nature of competition to cater to various economic 
 classes in the community, and this is an entirely different phenome- 
 non from that in the case of the gas company charging two different 
 prices for an article according to the use to which it is put. Every 
 retailer considers the class to which he will cater. Retailers tell 
 us that such is the case. One will say, " We try to cater to the 
 fashionable, wealthy people, the high-toned people." Another 
 will say: " I do not try to reach the so-called ' best people '; 
 I try to cater to the middle class. My training fits me better to 
 cater to this middle class than to cater to the fashionable people. 
 If I find that I can do this too, very well; but I especially cater 
 to the middle class." 1 We find that at stores like Marshall Field's 
 they recognize the various classes of the community and try to 
 reach the various classes of the community by their basement 
 department, and by their first floor, and the upper floors. But 
 that does not mean the absence of competition in the business as 
 a whole; but, taking the business as a whole, it competes with other 
 retail establishments in Chicago. Here we have a different class 
 
 1 It must not be overlooked that there is a variation in cost of doing a retail 
 business dependent upon the class of people to which a particular retailer caters. 
 Over against the higher prices charged, let us say by a fashionable grocer, we have 
 to put the higher quality of service. People of wealth and fashion require prompt 
 service, involving expense. Also, frequently the shops that cater to fashionable 
 people give very long credit and lose heavily in many cases. These are consider- 
 ations of a different kind from those mentioned in the text.
 
 206 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 price from that we have considered. We have a competitive class 
 price which, if the competition is perfect, yields no surplus. This 
 does not mean that some will not gain more than others in com- 
 petitive business. The gain is in proportion to the output of 
 energy. 
 
 Monopoly Price High Price. It is often said, and frequently 
 even in judicial decisions, that the monopolist can charge any price 
 that he pleases. We have already seen that this is not the case. 
 The law of monopoly price shows that the price, even in the case 
 of monopoly, is determined by economic forces. It is conceivable 
 that there may be cases in which monopoly price will exactly coin- 
 cide with competitive price, although the probabilities would be 
 against a frequent coincidence of this kind. There are also cases 
 where monopoly price may be even lower than competitive price. 
 If a monopolist should be able to effect great savings as compared 
 with the expense of doing business under competition, it could 
 theoretically happen that the price which would yield the largest 
 net returns would be a lower price than would be possible under 
 competition. Probably, and in fact almost certainly, under a 
 condition of competition, letters could not be carried as cheaply 
 as they are. 
 
 Generally there are strong reasons for the position that mo- 
 nopoly price is high price. Monopoly is formed for the sake of 
 gain. Gain may be secured in two ways by monopoly : first, 
 through economies of production; and it is alleged by trust pro- 
 moters that these economies are a chief motive in their activity. 
 There are some gains of this kind, but it is too early to say precisely 
 what they are. When we compare a monopolistic business with 
 a competitive business organized on such a scale as to secure the 
 maximum of efficiency, the gains of competition in alertness and 
 inventiveness, stimulated by rivalry, have recently been too little 
 considered. 
 
 The second source of gain in monopoly is found in the ability to 
 charge high price. In confirmation of the position that monopoly 
 price is high price, we may refer to history, the utterances of which 
 seem to be clear and distinct. At any rate, there can be no doubt 
 that, in the opinion of historians who have treated the subject,
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 207 
 
 monopoly means high price. Hume, in his treatment of monop- 
 oly in his History of England, speaks of the price of monopolized 
 articles as exorbitant, and cites the price of salt, the price of which 
 had been raised by monopoly tenfold and even more. The pro- 
 duction or sale of salt, or both, is frequently a government mo- 
 nopoly, and it is generally conceded that in all cases of monopoly 
 the price has been so extremely high as to be a real popular griev- 
 ance; and it is generally necessary to inflict severe penalties to 
 prevent the people from securing the salt at a lower price from 
 non-authorized sources. But of still greater significance are the 
 results of the investigations of the Industrial Commission of the 
 United States, as seen in the Preliminary Report of 1900 (Vol. I 
 of the complete report). It is there made evident that when 
 monopoly appears in a form at all clear and well-defined, the 
 tendency is plain to increase the margin between the prices of 
 finished products and raw materials. 1 
 
 The courts of the world have made it clear in their judicial ut- 
 terances that they regard monopoly price as high price; and, as 
 their opinions are based upon cases actually brought before them, 
 we cannot do otherwise than attach great importance to their 
 view. 
 
 Wherever commissions have been formed with power to regulate 
 monopoly price, and these commissions have been comprised of 
 independent and strong men, there has been a marked tendency 
 to reduce monopoly price; because unregulated monopoly price 
 has been found to be excessive and unjust. The judicially minded 
 Railroad Rate Commission of Wisconsin affords an illustration. 
 This Commission has authorized a higher price in a few cases, but 
 generally has been forced to lower prices, although in the notable 
 case of passenger rates it did not go so far as the legislature. The 
 investigations of the Railroad Rate Commission led the members 
 to believe that a reduction from three cents to two and one half 
 cents per mile for all the leading railways in Wisconsin was just; 
 whereas, subsequently, the legislature lowered the rate to two cents 
 
 1 See Report in Vol. I (Industrial ^ Commission), by Professor J. W. Jenks.on 
 " Industrial Combinations and Prices," pp. 39-57 ; and also Chap. VIII, " Prices," 
 in the same author's work, The Trust Problem.
 
 208 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 per mile. But even the decision of the Commission (which was 
 accepted by the railways) was a reduction of over 16 per cent. 
 Investigations held have resulted very generally in a lower price 
 for gas. All important investigations of street-car service in the 
 great cities of the United States have terminated in the conclusion 
 that the monopoly price of five cents per passenger is a high price. 
 The recent settlements with the street-car companies of Chicago 
 have been based upon an agreement to maintain a five-cent fare 
 and to give to the city of Chicago 55 per cent of the net gains. 
 According to the statements of the interested parties, even this will 
 leave a very handsome return for the owners of the street-car 
 properties. 
 
 In the next place, we refer to the experience and observation of 
 men when they have had dealings with well-defined monopolies. 
 The express companies and the oil business afford illustrations 
 falling within the experience and observation of nearly all readers 
 and students of this work. 
 
 Monopolies and the Distribution of Wealth. We have not the 
 precise statistical data which will enable us to state the exact 
 influence of monopoly upon the distribution of wealth. We have, 
 however, sufficient data to warrant the opinion that the high 
 price of monopoly and the gains resulting from the exclusive posi- 
 tion of the monopolist give us a large privileged class in countries 
 of modern civilization, but especially in the United States. An 
 advantage of the monopolist in the United States is found in the 
 law of monopoly price, coupled with the failure to regulate monop- 
 oly as carefully in our country as it has been regulated in Europe, 
 generally speaking. Ours is a country in which there is large 
 wealth, in which wealth is easily acquired, and in which conse- 
 quently people spend freely. Monopoly price must, then, be excep- 
 tionally high price and yield exceptional gains. Even when the 
 increment of price is comparatively small, it has large significance 
 in the case of the sale of a vast number of units of services or com- 
 modities. The difference between a four-cent street-car fare and 
 a five-cent street-car fare may not appear to be great, but it is a 
 difference of 25 per cent and is enormous. 
 
 All the many investigations that have been held recently in
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 209 
 
 various lines of business (especially in railways, beef industry, 
 coal mining, etc.). point to monopoly as a prime cause of the so- 
 called swollen fortunes of this country. In this and other countries 
 some histories of families distinguished for wealth have been written, 
 and probably few if any cases could be found in which some mo- 
 nopoly element had not entered. Various lists of rich men have 
 been published, among them one published by the New York Sun 
 in 1855, and one published by the New York Tribune in 1892. 
 These lists cannot by any means be presumed to be accurate, and 
 yet they do afford very considerable evidence of the sources of 
 large fortunes, and point to monopoly as a prime cause of the mod- 
 ern enormous fortunes. This is a subject which in itself would 
 require a larger book than the present one for adequate treatment. 
 The student must attempt by observation and study to carry for- 
 ward the lines of investigation and thought here suggested, being 
 constantly on his guard against undue haste in generalization. 
 
 Public Policy with Respect to Monopolies. It is possible to 
 throw out only a few suggestions in this place. As many monopo- 
 lies have come as a result of underlying laws of industrial evolu- 
 tion, they cannot all be abolished. Experience and the nature of 
 industries like railways, gas works, etc., falling under the head of 
 " public utilities," so called, should be conclusive. We must have 
 monopoly in these cases, and the only question we are concerned 
 with is, " What kind of monopolies shall we have ? " Again, we 
 cannot abolish monopoly simply as a result of legislative enact- 
 ment. The anti-trust laws of our states, so generally failures, 
 should be conclusive as to this point. On the other hand, legis- 
 lation is not powerless, but it must be in accord with the laws of 
 industrial evolution. The problem is abolition of undesirable 
 monopoly where this is feasible; and very generally regulation 
 rather than destruction. Here, again, we have the experience 
 of the United States and of other modern nations as confirmation. 
 
 We may, to begin with, admit that unregulated monopolies in 
 private hands have always been odious and are opposed to the 
 principle of the laws of civilized nations. They are opposed to 
 that endeavor to secure equality of opportunity which is funda- 
 mental in modern democracy and which manifests itself as a red
 
 210 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 thread running through American history. Even George Wash- 
 ington, generally looked upon as so calm and self-contained, 
 denounced monopolizers and wished they might be " hunted down 
 as pests of society " and " hanged on a gallows five times higher 
 than the one prepared for Haman." * It is not so much high price 
 that disturbs the modern man as it is inequality of opportunity; 
 and this general sentiment has been very clearly and forcibly 
 expressed in court decisions. It makes little impression upon the 
 American public when it is attempted to show that the Standard 
 Oil Company has lowered price. The enormous fortunes to which 
 it has given rise suggest that price has been higher than it should 
 be, yielding far greater than competitive gains; but even if it could 
 be proved that the price had been voluntarily lowered, it would 
 not be convincing, because we are disturbed by the alleged engross- 
 ment of opportunities by a few members of the community and 
 not open to others. Nor would it satisfy the American public to 
 be convinced of the sincerity of the professed benevolence and of 
 the personal integrity of the leaders of this gigantic undertaking. 
 The question is one of the action of economic forces, largely im- 
 personal; the leaders are often really coerced by these forces; 
 and from one point of view are to be looked upon as their 
 victims. 
 
 Obviously, the first step in a treatment of monopolies is to dis- 
 criminate between monopolies owned and operated by organized 
 society (that is, nation, state, or city, and managed in the general 
 interest) and private monopoly. If it is true that a certain portion 
 of the industrial field is naturally monopolistic, special privilege 
 can be removed by government ownership. This is the first and 
 most obvious method. The difficulties of government ownership 
 are such, however, that another method is by many advocated 
 as preferable and is, as a matter of fact, being thoroughly tried 
 in the case of railways in the United States. And that is the method 
 of public control of monopolies privately owned and operated. 
 The public control, to secure equality of opportunity, must so 
 regulate monopolies and limit price that the gains will be no higher 
 than those produced by equally wise investments and equally wise 
 1 Bullock, Essays on the Monetary History of the United States, p. 67.
 
 MONOPOLY 211 
 
 and prudent management in the field of competition. 1 Some- 
 times it is stated that owners of railways and other monopolistic 
 enterprises should have a competitive return upon all the money 
 that they have invested. This would give them a position of spe- 
 cial privilege, inasmuch as in the competitive field a great deal of 
 money is lost. It is only wise investment and careful management 
 in the field of competition that can secure returns equal or supe- 
 rior to the current rates of interest. Imprudently invested capi- 
 tal is lost in the field of competition; and when it is imprudently 
 and unwisely invested in the field of monopoly, it cannot justly 
 claim any return. 
 
 Finally, democratic sentiment demands that there should be no 
 needless extension of the field of monopoly through favoritism, 
 as seen in rebates and special rates of railway transportation com- 
 panies. 
 
 The Relation of Monopoly to Trusts. The development of 
 industry is treated elsewhere in this work, and it is shown that, as 
 a result of the forces inherent in industrial society, we pass over 
 from labor aided with few and simple implements, scarcely more 
 than an extension of hands and feet, so to speak, to labor aided 
 by increasingly complicated and costly tools, and then we find 
 labor supplemented and even replaced by machines, ushering 
 in the era of capitalism; and, as this transition is made, industry 
 is conducted on an ever larger and larger scale. The business unit 
 grows from the small, isolated shop to such a mammoth concern as 
 the United States Steel Corporation, owning an appreciable propor- 
 
 1 This does not mean that in the case of old enterprises price must always be so 
 reduced that the gains shall yield a competitive return only on the physical value 
 of a plant. The principle of vested rights or interests has to be given a certain 
 r&le. These have often been created by society rather than by private persons, and 
 faith must be kept. In the case of railways and the telegraph, the American nation 
 and states have deliberately encouraged a wasteful policy of competition which 
 is in large measure responsible for high capitalization. It would not be right 
 to place upon holders of these properties all the burdens of a mistaken public 
 policy in the past. What is needed is to declare a public policy for the future 
 and to base returns for the future upon future actual investments in the case of 
 public utilities. In any case, we should have a physical valuation of railways, 
 gas works, etc., as a help in determining fair prices for present and future. Now 
 and here we can do no more than to throw out these suggestions in regard to a 
 pressing present problem of great magnitude.
 
 212 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tion of the wealth of a vast nation. These large business units, as a 
 result of evolution, are commonly designated as trusts; but they 
 present simply the problems of large-scale industry unless they com- 
 prise elements of monopoly. This indeed very often, perhaps usually, 
 happens in the case of the largest industrial establishments. They 
 have been aided by rebates and other favors from railways, and 
 they have made themselves master of peculiarly rich and espe- 
 cially limited supplies of natural resources, such as petroleum oil, 
 anthracite coal, and the Mesabi iron range. The trust problem 
 resolves itself into two classes of problems: first, the class of prob- 
 lems belonging to large-scale business; and second, the class of 
 problems falling under monopoly. The discussion of so-called 
 trusts can be profitably considered under these two categories. 
 There is no magic in the mere word " trust," although it seems to 
 have power to awaken alarm and has helped produce precipitate 
 legislative action; whereas action must be preceded by an analy- 
 sis of the trust problem into its proper elements to make possible 
 its satisfactory solution. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Has bigness anything to do with monopoly? Do you know any small 
 business which is a monopoly ? Do you know any very large business which 
 is keenly competitive? Contrast a state of competition with a state of 
 monopoly. 
 
 2. Define monopoly and discuss each point in the definition. 
 
 3. Describe as fully as you can the relation of industrial evolution to 
 the idea of monopoly. 
 
 4. Do you think that monopolists now show a worse spirit than formerly ? 
 a better spirit? Describe the monopoly established by Joseph in Egypt. 
 (Genesis, Chap, xlvii). What good effects did it have? Is it apparent 
 that it had evil effects? 
 
 5. What do we understand by partial monopolies ? What is there, strictly 
 speaking, illogical in the term ? Is this a sufficient reason for not using it ? 
 
 6. Contrast land-ownership with monopoly. 
 
 7. Explain the importance of classification of monopolies, and especially 
 of distinguishing between private and public monopolies. 
 
 8. State the main classes of monopolies, and give the divisions and sub- 
 divisions in each class. 
 
 9. A public tobacco monopoly exists in France and produces large revenues. 
 The business is said otherwise to be well managed. Do you see any benefits
 
 MONOPOLY 
 
 213 
 
 that would accrue from the establishment of such a monopoly in the United 
 States? any evil effects? 
 
 10. Define monopoly price and show how it is determined. 
 
 11. What does class price mean? Compare monopoly class price with 
 competitive class price. Explain "use price." 
 
 12. Contrast "commodity competition" with "business unit competition." 
 
 13. Why do we think of monopoly price as high price ? Do you know any 
 monopoly price which is a low price? What do you mean by high price? 
 by low price ? 
 
 14. What relation has monopoly to large fortunes? to small fortunes? 
 W T hat, if any, to poverty? 
 
 15. What is the wise public policy with respect to monopolies ? 
 
 16. Describe the relation of trusts to monopolies. 
 
 LITERATURE 
 
 BAKER, C. W. Monopolies and the People, Part II. 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Introduction to the Study of Economics, Chap. XI. " Trust 
 
 Literature : A Survey and Criticism." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 
 
 Vol. XV, 1901, pp. 167-216. Reprinted in Ripley's Trusts, Pools, 
 
 and Corporations, pp. 428-473. 
 ELY, R. T. Monopolies and Trusts, Chap. Ill, pp. 102-104; also Chap. VI, 
 
 pp. 229-231. 
 HOBSON, J. A. Evolution of Modern Capitalism, new and revised ed., 1907, 
 
 Chap. IX. 
 
 JENKS, J. W. The Trust Problem. 
 National Civic Federation Report, 1907 : Municipal and Private Operation 
 
 of Public Utilities. 3 vols. 
 
 PRICE, W. H. The English Patents of Monopoly. 
 Report of the Chicago Conference on Trusts. 
 Report of the United States Industrial Commission, Vols. I and II. 
 RIPLEY, W. Z. Trusts, Pools, and Corporations; Railway Problems. 
 SHAW, ALBERT. Municipal Government in Great Britain; also, Municipal 
 
 Government in Continental Europe, Chap. VI.
 
 CHAPTER XIV 
 MONEY 
 
 THE vast system of valuation and exchange, which is the most 
 characteristic single feature of present-day economy, rests upon 
 the use of money. Some economic writers have pictured an im- 
 aginary primitive state of "barter economy," in which, before the 
 use of money, goods were exchanged directly for goods. But what 
 little definite information there is on this point leads to the belief 
 that about as soon as men began to exchange things, and conse- 
 quently to attach exchange value to them, they began to use some 
 kind of money some commodity or commodities for which things 
 were generally exchanged, and in terms of which the values of other 
 things were generally measured. 
 
 These earliest forms of money were crude and simple, but they 
 sufficed to meet simple needs. As exchange economy has ad- 
 vanced through the growth of individual and industrial specializa- 
 tion and the localization of industry to the present complex division 
 of labor, the monetary system has developed pari passu, the most 
 conspicuous feature of this development in modern times being the 
 growing importance of credit as a means of effecting exchanges. 
 Industrial and commercial progress has led to monetary progress, 
 and has, in turn, been stimulated and made possible by it. 
 
 Various Meanings of the Word "Money." The word "money," 
 like so many other terms with which economics has to deal, has 
 in common usage no restricted technical meaning, but may denote 
 any one of a number of different things. It sometimes means 
 individual wealth of any sort. A "monied" man is simply a 
 wealthy man. This is, however, only a colloquial and purely de- 
 rivative meaning. A second, and very common, use of the word is 
 in the sense of generally exchangeable purchasing power, whether 
 
 214
 
 MONEY 
 
 215 
 
 this be embodied in concrete forms of money, or exist only in 
 the intangible form of credit. Money in this sense is synonymous 
 with "money funds." The "money market" is the market for 
 loanable money funds. When we speak of "money income," 
 "money expenditures," "money investments," etc., we refer to 
 this exchangeable purchasing power. 
 
 Other meanings of the word " money " suggest that, for some 
 purposes, a distinction may he made between "money" and 
 credit instruments. But to look for any definite line of demar- 
 cation, consistently followed in common usage, or even in eco- 
 nomic writings, would be a vain search. The element of credit 
 is found in most forms of money, even, as we shall see, in some 
 kinds of metallic money. A useful and important distinction, how- 
 ever, is made by the very common practice of restricting the term 
 "money" to those instruments of general acceptability which pass 
 freely from hand to hand as media of exchange. The particular 
 things included in this third concept of money vary for different 
 periods and for different countries. In the United States this 
 freely exchangeable medium includes the metallic and paper money 
 issued by the federal government, together with national bank notes. 
 Checks drawn by individuals upon their bank accounts are not 
 money, or money instruments, in this sense, because they do not 
 pass freely from hand to hand as media of exchange. They can be 
 used only in making payments to persons who know and have con- 
 fidence in the drawer, indorser, or holder of the check. 
 
 This third meaning of the word " money" possesses, as has been 
 suggested, the sanction of a very common and prevalent usage; it 
 corresponds, moreover, to the technical definition given to the word 
 by many economic writers, and to the official usage of the United 
 States Treasury. Some writers, however, have drawn the line 
 between money and other means of payment somewhat differ- 
 ently, either refusing to count bank notes as money, thus limiting 
 the term to money instruments issued by the government, or nar- 
 rowing the application of the term yet further by using it to denote 
 only metallic money, all other media of exchange being counted 
 only as promises to pay money. 
 
 Yet another, and still more restricted, meaning is attached to the
 
 2l6 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 word when it is employed to denote only that part of the stock of 
 metallic money which serves as a standard of -value as well as a 
 medium of exchange. Although this extreme limitation of the 
 meaning of the word " money" is neither common nor justifiable, 
 the distinction suggested by it is a fundamental one. For, as 
 we shall see presently, the value of all other media of exchange 
 is determined by their relation to what is best distinguished by 
 calling it standard money. 
 
 All these different uses of the word " money " imply distinctions of 
 greater or less significance, but for purposes of economic analysis 
 the most important concepts are the second, third, and last in the 
 foregoing enumeration. Recognition of the fact that exchangeable 
 purchasing power, money instruments of general acceptability, and 
 the standard of value are different things is indispensable to clear 
 thinking in this field. In this chapter the word " money " will be 
 employed in the sense of money instruments of general accept- 
 ability. 
 
 Metallic Money. The earliest and simplest forms of money 
 were commodities. Particular commodities came to serve as 
 money, not because they were arbitrarily designated as such by 
 king or chieftain, but because they possessed some properties which 
 made them exceptionably exchangeable. In some cases a primi- 
 tive community came to use a commodity as money because it was 
 something for which they had a dependable "foreign market" - 
 something, that is, which they customarily sold to other communi- 
 ties in exchange for their products. In other cases a commodity 
 which a community did not itself produce, but which it got only in 
 the course of trade with other communities, became the money 
 commodity. Or, if for any reason a particular commodity came 
 to be particularly esteemed as a mark of wealth or a badge of social 
 prestige, it was very apt to be used as money. But whatever the 
 original ground of the choice, a commodity which a community 
 once began to think of as money had its exchangeability, and con- 
 sequently its suitability for monetary uses, increased in a cumulative 
 way, just as to-day most of us are willing to accept anything as 
 money which we think we can use as money. 
 
 A great variety of commodities have at one time or another been
 
 MONEY 
 
 217 
 
 used as money. Some typical examples are cattle, grain, furs, oil, 
 salt, tobacco, ivory, shells, and tea. But with the advance of politi- 
 cal and economic civilization the metals have, through the process 
 of the survival of the fittest, proven themselves everywhere to.be 
 preeminently and indisputably the best money commodities. 
 Copper, silver, and gold have each in turn been chosen as the prin- 
 cipal money metal of the civilized world, the transition from the 
 cheaper to the dearer metals indicating the growth of exchange and 
 the consequent need of larger money units. 
 
 Metals, and especially the precious metals, have certain qualities 
 that give them a peculiar fitness to serve as money. They are 
 durable, easily recognized and tested, and may be divided into 
 homogeneous units of convenient form and weight. Moreover, as 
 compared with most other commodities, the precious metals are 
 relatively stable in value a fact that arises in part from their 
 durability, for any one year's output of the mines makes but a 
 comparatively small addition to the total stock of metallic money. 
 
 Coinage. When metals were first used as money, they passed 
 from hand to hand simply by weight, or, in some cases, in the form 
 of ornaments. Coinage speedily developed, however, as a con- 
 venient way of certifying to the weight and fineness of money units. 1 
 
 Such a guarantee is naturally of little avail unless it is generally 
 recognized as authoritative. On this account the coinage of money 
 has almost universally been regarded as a prerogative of the sov- 
 ereign. In England, even under the divided sovereignty of the 
 middle ages, the coining of gold and silver was generally a privilege 
 belonging to the king alone. The lesser feudal lords and the char- 
 tered cities issued token coins, made of the baser metals, and in- 
 tended especially for local use, but if they possessed the right of 
 coining the precious metals, it was through a special grant of the 
 king. 
 
 Seigniorage. Sovereigns have in the past very often viewed 
 the monopoly of coinage as an opportunity for personal profit. By 
 
 1 The names of many ancient coins and of some modern ones are also the 
 names of weights, although it has generally happened that through successive 
 debasements of the. coinage these names have lost their original significance. 
 The Greek talent, the Jewish shekel, the Roman as, the English pound, and the 
 French livre are familiar examples.
 
 2l8 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 calling in the stock of metallic money in the country for recoinage, 
 they have frequently reduced the weight of coins without changing 
 their nominal value, thus increasing the number of coins, so that a 
 handsome profit was netted for the royal treasury. Debasement 
 of the currency was a favorite financial expedient of Henry 
 VIII, of England, and of Philip the Fair and Louis XIV, of 
 France. 
 
 Somewhat less reprehensible in theory, although amounting to 
 about the same thing in its effects, was the common practice of 
 making a charge for coinage, called seigniorage. This practice 
 was based on the idea that it was possible to maintain a dif- 
 ference between the value of a coin and the value of the bullion 
 put into it. 1 A great deal has been written about the possibility 
 of seigniorage, for the subject is one that involves considerations 
 that are fundamental in monetary theory. It has been often said, 
 for example, that it is the "government stamp," rather than the 
 metallic content, that gives value to a coin. Leaving aside the 
 matter of limited or subsidiary coinage (which will be considered 
 presently), we may dispose of this statement by saying that if it 
 means that the use of certain metals as money decreases the supply 
 of them available for other purposes, and thus increases their value, 
 it is a truism; but if it means that in coinage we can add an arbi- 
 trary and intangible element of value to the metallic content of the 
 coin, the statement is a false and misleading doctrine that has been 
 disproved over and over again by the monetary experience of 
 almost every country. 
 
 There is, however, a stronger statement of the theory of seignior- 
 age. If the only way in which I can convert bullion into a medium 
 of exchange is by being content with 750 ounces of money for every 
 looo ounces of bullion I take to the mint, will not the coins have a 
 value one third greater than that of the metal they contain ? May 
 not their "metallic content" be said to be, in a figurative sense, 
 one third more than their weight, because they cost me that much 
 more in bullion? If their bullion value sinks below this point, 
 bullion will not be brought to the mint, as it would be worth more 
 
 1 Under Philip the Fair, of France, the seigniorage charge went as high as 
 50 per cent. Charges of from 2 to 15 per cent were more common.
 
 MONEY 
 
 219 
 
 than the coins one could get for it ; just as when the value of the 
 coins rises above this point the supply of bullion would be stimu- 
 lated so that as a result the value of the coins would tend to maintain 
 this fixed relation to the value of bullion. Confidence in the sta- 
 bility of the government may be assumed in this reasoning; and 
 as a matter of fact, it is probable that in a completely isolated 
 community the government could, through wise and careful regu- 
 lations, maintain a constant rate of profit on the coinage, with- 
 out endangering the stability of the monetary system. 
 
 The fundamental difficulty with seigniorage is, however, that in 
 foreign trade coins pass current only as bullion, so that when 
 seigniorage was charged, the prices of imported goods, measured 
 in money, were necessarily higher than their prices measured in 
 bullion, by an amount equal to the seigniorage. It was impossible 
 that one ratio could long be maintained between the value of coined 
 money and the value of bullion in domestic trade and another ratio 
 in foreign trade. The interdependence of the prices of all kinds 
 of goods prevented that. Money prices, in general, always rose ; 
 that is, the value of the coins sank to the level of the value of the 
 bullion they contained. Under these conditions no one would 
 voluntarily undergo the loss inseparable from taking bullion to the 
 mint for coinage, and with the cessation of coinage the profits from 
 coinage stopped. Every possible expedient, short of the absolute 
 prohibition of foreign trade, was tried by sovereigns in their efforts 
 to retain these profits. 1 But market forces were found to be 
 stronger than royal regulations, which at best only served to retard 
 somewhat the depression in the value of the official coinage. 
 About the only effective way of getting seigniorage profits was for 
 the sovereign to admit that the coins in circulation possessed only 
 their bullion value, and then to call in the currency for recoinage 
 
 1 The use of any other circulating medium than the official one was prohibited ; 
 no one was allowed to sell imported gold or silver, whether in bullion or coin, 
 save to the royal mint ; if there were mines within the country, they were some- 
 times prohibited from disposing of their products except to the royal mint ; gold- 
 smiths were forbidden to melt down coin or to purchase more bullion than they 
 needed, and this they were forbidden to buy at less than the mint price; restric- 
 tions were placed on the export of bullion ; these and other similar methods were 
 tried, but all to no avail. Cf. W. Lexis, article "Miinzwesen," in Handworterbuch 
 der Stuatswissenschaften.
 
 220 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 into smaller pieces, in the manner that has already been mentioned, 
 thus starting afresh with a new seigniorage charge. The result 
 was invariably a repetition of the process of a more or less rapid 
 depreciation in the purchasing power of the coins, leading often to 
 further debasements of the currency. 
 
 Modern nations have abandoned the attempt to secure profits 
 from their monopoly of the coinage. Since 1666 England has 
 made no charge whatever for coining bullion into standard money. 1 
 Most of the countries of continental Europe make a charge just 
 sufficient to cover the expense of coinage. This charge is some- 
 times called seigniorage, but it is usually, and more properly, called 
 brassage. The United States made no coinage charge until 1853, 
 when a charge of one half of i per cent was made for coining 
 standard money. This was reduced in 1873 and was abandoned 
 entirely in 1875. At present the United States exchanges gold 
 coins, weight for weight, for bullion of standard fineness (nine 
 tenths gold, one tenth copper) brought to the mint in lots of one 
 hundred dollars or more in value. For crude bullion, or bullion 
 not of standard fineness, gold coins are exchanged containing as 
 much fine gold as is contained in the bullion, less a trifling charge 
 for assaying, refining, and for the alloy. 2 
 
 Instead of viewing coinage as a profitable prerogative of the 
 government, we have come to view it as a government duty, to be 
 performed at government expense. The question of seigniorage 
 versus gratuitous coinage is no longer a live issue. But the student 
 who has grasped the significance of the lesson contained in the his- 
 tory of seigniorage has taken an important step toward the under- 
 
 1 In practice most of the gold bullion coined in England is supplied to the mint 
 by the Bank of England, which is required by law to purchase it at the minimum 
 price of 3 175. gd. per ounce. An ounce of bullion makes 3 175. io$d. in 
 gold coin, the difference going to compensate the bank for the delay involved in 
 getting the bullion coined at the mint. In the United States the waiting devolves 
 upon the government, for gold coins, or, at the option of the depositor, checks 
 upon United States subtreasuries or upon depository banks are paid to depositors 
 as soon as their bullion can be weighed and assayed. 
 
 2 The coinage mints are at Philadelphia, San Francisco, New Orleans, and 
 Denver. In addition there are assay offices at New York, Carson, Boise, Helena, 
 Charlotte, St. Louis, Deadwood, and Seattle, which receive bullion on the same 
 terms as the mints, plus an additional charge of one eighth of i per cent.
 
 MONEY 221 
 
 standing of monetary theory. There is no mysterious element of 
 intangible value created by the operation of coinage. The coinage 
 of standard money is now in law, and always has been in fact, a 
 device for dividing the standard money metal into convenient units 
 of certified weight and fineness. 
 
 The Standard of Value. We have seen in an earlier chapter 
 that prices are exchange values measured in terms of money. 
 Goods and services are exchanged for money in certain ratios, and 
 these ratios constitute the prices of the goods and services. Some 
 writers have made a distinction between the functions which 
 money performs as a medium of exchange, and its functions as a 
 measure of value. These are not, however, two different functions, 
 but merely two different aspects of the same thing. By the very 
 process of exchanging a commodity for money, we of necessity 
 measure its value in terms of money, and only as a medium of ex- 
 change does money measure value. We may speak of a pound 
 weight as an instrument used in weighing or as a measure of weight, 
 but we would all recognize that this refers only to two aspects of 
 the same thing. 
 
 In the United States the actual medium of exchange with which 
 we measure values is heterogeneous in that it comprises a variety 
 of coins, made from different metals, together with several kinds of 
 paper money of many different denominations. But it is homo- 
 geneous in that first, all these different forms of money are alike in 
 name, that is, they are dollars, or multiples or fractions of a 
 dollar, and second, these various kinds of dollars are identical 
 in value. This familiar and very satisfactory condition of uni- 
 formity in the units in which we measure value does not, however, 
 suggest to us the real nature of the value of money in the way that a 
 less perfect monetary system would. 
 
 It would be possible to have a number of different monetary 
 units, just as the weight or size of an object may be stated in terms 
 of either the metric system or the English system of weights and 
 measures. In fact, before the United States had an adequate 
 monetary system of its own, the actual medium of exchange con- 
 sisted largely of English, French, Spanish, and Portuguese coins, 
 and there were as many different ways of stating prices, that is, of
 
 222 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 measuring values, as there were units of value. 1 Nor does the 
 mere name of "dollar" give to different pieces of money a uniform 
 value. The silver dollar of Mexico is worth only about half as 
 much as the silver dollar of the United States, although it is of ap- 
 proximately the same size. More significant, however, is the fact 
 that in the United States we have had at different times "dollars" 
 of unequal value. 
 
 What is it, then, that gives uniformity to the dollar as a unit of 
 value in our present monetary system ? To say that various kinds 
 of money are equal in value because they will purchase the same 
 amounts of goods is, obviously, to argue in a circle. But the an- 
 swer is found in the fact that they are interchangeable, and so long 
 as any number of kinds of money, all named in dollar units, are 
 freely exchangeable, dollar for dollar, it is impossible that a dollar 
 in one kind of money should be worth more than a dollar in any 
 other kind of money. We do not refer here to the fact that the 
 different kinds of money are exchanged for each other at par in 
 business transactions and in banking, for this is a result, rather 
 than a cause, of the uniform value of the money units. The ex- 
 changeability that underlies the uniform value of our different 
 kinds of money is maintained by the federal government. 
 
 All coins smaller than a dollar are by law exchangeable at the 
 United States Treasury for "lawful money," which includes gov- 
 ernment notes, silver dollars, and gold coins. Government notes, 
 in turn, are simply promises to pay, which are redeemable in gold 
 at the government Treasury. While there is no definite legal man- 
 date requiring the redemption of silver dollars in gold, yet the cur- 
 
 1 An instructive bit of monetary experience may be found in the efforts of 
 some of the colonies to reduce this foreign money, especially Spanish money, 
 to the English system of pounds, shillings, and pence, in which accounts were 
 generally kept. They were not content with a simple official statement of the 
 actual ratios between the different value units, but sought to give an artificially 
 enhanced value to the foreign coins by increasing the number of shillings to which 
 they were to be considered equivalent. The result was not, however, an increase 
 in the value of the coins, but a decrease in the value of the nominal "shilling" 
 in which accounts were kept. This was the origin of the now rapidly vanishing 
 use of the word "shilling" as equivalent to 12^ cents in some localities and to 
 1 6$ cents in others. The student may find an instructive parallel in this experi- 
 ence and the official statements of coin values by which sovereigns tried to retain 
 their seigniorage profits.
 
 MONEY 
 
 223 
 
 rency act of 1900 makes it the duty of the Secretary of the Treasury 
 to maintain all other forms of money at a parity with gold a 
 requirement which means that he would have to redeem silver 
 dollars in gold if such action should at any time be needed to 
 maintain their parity. Gold certificates and silver certificates, are 
 simply a mechanism for putting gold and silver money into circu- 
 lation in convenient form. They are analogous to warehouse re- 
 ceipts, because they represent gold coins and silver dollars that are 
 stored in the government Treasury to the full amount of the certifi- 
 cates issued, and which may be obtained at any time in exchange 
 for the certificates. National bank notes, which constitute a large 
 part of our actual circulating medium, are redeemed at the federal 
 Treasury in government notes. In practice the government is con- 
 tinually receiving all kinds of money, including silver dollars, and 
 exchanging other kinds of money for them. 
 
 The significant thing is that all other kinds of money are exchange- 
 able, directly or indirectly, for gold coin. In the case of gold coin, 
 there is* a further kind of exchangeability the unlimited and 
 free convertibility of gold coin and gold bullion. So long as any 
 one can secure gold coin in any amount for the same weight of gold 
 bullion of standard fineness, and so long as gold coin can be freely 
 melted down into gold bullion, it is impossible that there should be 
 any difference between the value of a gold coin and the value of its 
 metallic content. We have, then, not only the interchangeability of 
 all parts of the circulating medium, but also the positive physical 
 identity of one part of it and the material of which this part is made. 
 Gold, whether in coin or bullion, constitutes the standard of value, 
 for it is the value of gold that fixes the value of the dollar. The 
 measuring of values in terms of dollars through the exchange of 
 goods and services for money of different sorts, the equalizing of 
 the values of dollars in all varieties of money through their ex- 
 changeability, and the automatic standardization of the value of 
 the dollar through the free and unlimited coinage of gold l ; these 
 are the fundamental facts of our monetary system. 
 
 1 In fixing the value of coins at the value of their metallic content, unlimited 
 coinage is of more importance than free coinage, as the history of seigniorage 
 shows. Some writers have emphasized the importance of the legal tender quality
 
 224 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Gold coins, because their value as bullion is equal to their value 
 as coins, constitute standard money. The gold dollar weighing 
 25.8 grains, and containing 23.22 grains of fine gold, is by law the 
 unit of value. The coinage of the gold dollar was discontinued in 
 1890, but the gold coins that are minted contain precisely this 
 amount of gold per dollar. 
 
 Limited Coinage. Gold is the only metal which is made into 
 coins by the United States government for any one who deposits 
 bullion at the mints or assay offices. All other coins are made 
 from metal purchased from time to time for that purpose as Con- 
 gress may direct. In none of these coins is the bullion worth as 
 much as the coin. In 1878, when the United States began the 
 limited coinage of silver dollars, the value of the 371^ grains of pure 
 silver in a silver dollar was about 89 cents. The value of silver de- 
 clined steadily until 1902, when 371^ grains of silver were worth 
 only 41 cents. Since that time there has been a slight upward move- 
 ment, but nevertheless the present (1908) bullion value of a silver 
 dollar is only about one half its value as a coin. The bullion value 
 of the smaller silver coins is still less, for they contain but 347.22 
 grains of silver to the dollar, while the bullion value of our nickel 
 and bronze coins is yet smaller, relatively. 
 
 Such coins are sometimes called "token coins," the implication 
 being that the fact that they pass from hand to hand at their full 
 nominal value is merely a matter of habit or usage, supported by 
 general acquiescence. More accurately, however, they are credit 
 coins, because the excess of their coin value over their bullion value 
 depends ultimately, as we have seen, upon the good faith and credit 
 of the government, evidenced by their redeemability in gold. If, 
 for example, a catastrophy should overthrow the present federal 
 government, and if the new government should refuse to recognize 
 the obligations of the old, nothing could prevent these coins from 
 sinking to their bullion value. 
 
 in this connection. But experience has shown that while the fact that money must 
 be accepted by a creditor at full value sometimes makes an otherwise undesirable 
 kind of money a "generally acceptable medium of exchange," it does not suffice 
 to maintain its value, so far as prices made after such money has been issued are 
 concerned.
 
 MONEY 
 
 225 
 
 A very considerable profit accrues to the government from this 
 limited coinage. The difference between the amount paid for 
 silver bullion from 1878 to 1907, and the value of the coins made 
 from it, amounted to $143,000,000. In the accounts of the federal 
 treasury this profit is called seigniorage, but it is to be carefully 
 distinguished from real seigniorage, a charge exacted for the 
 conversion of standard bullion into standard coin. If the federal 
 government should issue a general balance sheet of the kind used 
 in corporation accounting, the credit element in its outstanding 
 limited coinage would properly appear as a liability, which might 
 be greater or less than the profits that had accrued on such coinage, 
 depending upon whether the present value of the bullion in the 
 coins happened to be greater or less than the prices which the gov- 
 ernment had paid for it. 
 
 Bimetallism. A monetary system like the present one of the 
 United States is a single standard system, because only one com- 
 modity is used as a standard of value. The double standard system, 
 under which two different commodities serve concurrently as 
 legal standards of value, has, however, been used in the past 
 by many governments, including our own, and its superiority 
 over the single standard system has been alleged by many advo- 
 cates. Practically the only commodities that civilized nations 
 have used as standards of value in modern times are gold and 
 silver. The question of the double standard resolves itself, 
 accordingly, into the question of the bimetallic standard, which 
 means in practice the unlimited coinage of both gold and 
 silver. 
 
 Bimetallism does not mean, in theory, as might be supposed, the 
 establishment of two different monetary units of different names, 
 one measured by the value of a certain amount of silver, the other 
 by the value of a certain amount of gold, prices being measured 
 according to convenience in terms of either unit. On the contrary, 
 it contemplates the establishment of one nominal unit, such as the 
 dollar, to be measured at the same time by the value of either a defi- 
 nite amount of gold or a definite amount of silver. More concretely 
 this means the opening of the mints to the unlimited coinage of both 
 gold and silver into dollars, or dollar multiples, the amount of silver 
 Q
 
 226 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 in a silver dollar and the amount of gold in a gold dollar being 
 established by law. 
 
 Many of the arguments that have been advanced by bimetallists 
 have related to the alleged immediate advantages to be secured 
 from the adoption of the double standard under particular condi- 
 tions of time and place. One argument, however, of more general 
 significance is based on the probable greater stability in value of 
 the double standard. Silver and gold are produced under some- 
 what different conditions, and are used for somewhat different pur- 
 poses. It has been suggested that tendencies toward fluctuations 
 in the value of silver and gold would, therefore, be as apt to be in 
 opposite directions as in the same direction, and that so far as they 
 were in opposite directions they would tend to counterbalance each 
 other. 
 
 Most opponents of bimetallism, while admitting that, if feasible, 
 it might possess some advantages, deny its possibility. The diffi- 
 culty is, they maintain, that while the ratio of the weight of gold in 
 the monetary unit to the weight of silver in the monetary unit has 
 to be fixed and definite, the ratio of the value of gold to the value of 
 silver is not fixed and definite, but is subject to the fluctuations 
 of the market. If one metal is relatively undervalued and the other 
 relatively overvalued by the legal ratio, the result will be that only 
 the overvalued metal will be brought to the mint for coinage, for the 
 undervalued metal will be worth no more than the overvalued one 
 as coin, but will be worth more as bullion. The actual result will 
 be, in such a case, not a bimetallic standard, but a single standard 
 composed of the metal which, at the mint ratio, is the cheaper. 
 Moreover, if, by a change in the relative market values of the two 
 metals, this one in turn becomes undervalued by the mint ratio, 
 the standard coins composed of that metal that are already in use 
 will, according to Gresham's law, 1 disappear from circulation, 
 being hoarded, melted down, or exported, and the other metal will 
 take its place as the actual standard of value. 
 
 1 Gresham's law is that "bad money drives out good,'"' or that "the cheaper 
 money drives out the dearer." Sir Thomas Gresham, master of the mint under 
 Queen Elizabeth, came to this conclusion as a result of his observation of the 
 difficulties encountered by that sovereign in her attempts to improve the condition 
 of the debased, worn, and mutilated coinage bequeathed to her by her predecessors.
 
 MONEY 
 
 227 
 
 
 All but the most extreme bimetallists would admit the impossi- 
 bility of establishing and maintaining a coinage ratio between the 
 two metals that would differ by any considerable margin from the 
 ratio corresponding to their market values, but they maintain that 
 a mint ratio established as nearly as possible to the prevailing 
 market ratio will have a steadying influence upon the latter that 
 will tend to prevent any wide divergence between the two. If one 
 metal should rise in value to such an extent that it would not pay 
 to use it as money, more of the other metal would be used for mone- 
 tary purposes, thus decreasing the supply of it available for other 
 uses and consequently enhancing its value. The net effect would 
 be, it is claimed, a tendency toward the equilibrium of the value of 
 the two metals at the coinage ratio. 
 
 The appeal to history has been used both by bimetallists and 
 their opponents. The claim of the monometallists that legal bi- 
 metallism is apt to mean actual monometallism, with the relatively 
 cheaper metal as the standard, has been substantiated many times 
 in the monetary experience of different nations. The automatic 
 change from one single standard to the other, following a change 
 in market values, is also a phenomenon that has been illustrated by 
 a large number of concrete cases. On the other hand, the bimetal- 
 lists are able to point to some apparently successful bimetallic sys- 
 tems, such as that of France in the eighteenth century. But it is a 
 significant fact that no real bimetallic system has been able to en- 
 dure for any considerable time except when the annual production of 
 gold and silver was relatively small and relatively stable, and where 
 international trade was a relatively unimportant item. There is no 
 scientific student of monetary problems who believes that it would 
 be possible for any nation to maintain independently the double 
 standard under the present conditions of a large and fluctuating 
 annual production of the precious metals, coupled with an inter- 
 national commerce of vast proportions. 
 
 International bimetallism, that is, the adoption by each of the 
 leading nations of a bimetallic standard, at a ratio fixed by national 
 agreement, has had many supporters, even among those who do not 
 believe in the practicability of national bimetallism, and repre- 
 sentatives of different nations have assembled in several inter-
 
 228 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 national monetary conferences for the discussion of this subject 
 International bimetallism would remove one difficulty experienced 
 in the attempts made by different nations to maintain independent 
 bimetallic systems at even slightly differing ratios, and that is, 
 the tendency for each metal to flow from the countries in which it is 
 relatively undervalued in the mint ratio to the countries in which 
 it is relatively overvalued. Other difficulties, however, would still 
 remain, and the possibility of maintaining an actual bimetallic 
 standard even under international agreement, supposing that were 
 possible, is open to very serious doubt. 
 
 The waning of public interest in the question of bimetallism in 
 recent years is of great significance, because it indicates that the 
 real moving forces behind the bimetallist propaganda have not been 
 any real or assumed points of superiority of general significance 
 that may be imputed to a multiple standard, but rather that certain 
 specific results that would flow from the adoption of bimetallism 
 at a particular time and place have been desired. More specific- 
 ally, bimetallism has been supported by those who have desired 
 "cheaper money," and these have been particularly active when 
 the monetary standard in actual use has been increasing in value; 
 that is, when prices in general have been decreasing. The recent 
 great increase in the world's production of gold has, temporarily at 
 least, taken bimetallism out of the list of economic problems of 
 general public interest. 
 
 Bimetallism in the United States. The national monetary sys- 
 tem was established by act of Congress in I792. 1 The mint was 
 opened to the free and unlimited coinage of both gold and silver, 
 the silver coins containing 371^ grains of fine metal per dollar, and 
 the gold coins 24! grains per dollar, the ratio of 15 to i being thus 
 established. It was soon found, however, that gold was worth in 
 the market slightly more than fifteen times as much as silver, and 
 
 1 The act of 1792 followed in detail the -recommendations of a Report of the 
 Establishment of a Mint, by Alexander Hamilton, then Secretary of the Treasury. 
 Hamilton incorporated some of the recommendations contained in earlier reports 
 by Robert Morris and Thomas Jefferson. Hamilton's Report has been frequently 
 reprinted, but it, together with the reports of Morris and Jefferson and other 
 pertinent documents, may be conveniently found in the Report of the International 
 Monetary Conference of 1878.
 
 MONEY 
 
 229 
 
 as a consequence but little gold was brought to the mint for coinage, 
 while the gold that was coined illustrated Gresham's law by speedily 
 disappearing from circulation. 
 
 Silver dollars, too, disappeared from circulation, but for another reason. 
 They were somewhat lighter than the Spanish dollars which were in general 
 circulation at the time, and would, under the operations of Gresham's law, 
 have driven the latter out of circulation, had it not been that the Spanish 
 dollar commanded a slight premium over the American dollar in ordinary 
 purchases. But the American dollars, on account of their new and attractive 
 appearance, could be used as 'dvantageously as the Spanish dollars in trade 
 with the Spanish possessions in America. They were consequently taken 
 from the country for that purpose, while Spanish dollars were brought 
 back and were often recoined into a larger number of American dollars. 
 This wasteful coinage of silver dollars was stopped in 1806 by order of 
 President Jefferson, leaving the mint open to the coinage only of gold, smaller 
 silver coins, and minor coins. As a matter of fact American coins made up 
 only an insignificant part of our circulating medium before 1834. 
 
 Realizing the impossibility of maintaining a gold coinage under 
 such conditions, Congress, in 1834, changed the legal ratio to 16 to i 
 by reducing the weight of the gold dollar. By this step, however, 
 they went too far in the other direction, for silver was undervalued 
 at this ratio, and while the number of gold coins increased, but little 
 silver was brought to the mint, and silver coins quickly disappeared 
 from circulation. In order to secure a supply of small change, 
 Congress was forced, in 1853, to abandon the principle of the free 
 and unlimited coinage of silver coins smaller than a dollar, and to 
 order that they should be coined, as at present, only from bullion 
 purchased by the government at the market price. At the same 
 time the weight of these subsidiary coins was reduced by one 
 seventh to insure their being retained in circulation. 
 
 The discovery of gold in California, in 1848, and in Australia, in 
 1851, suddenly increased the world's supply of gold by an unprece- 
 dented amount. In fact, the careful estimates of Dr. Soetbeer indi- 
 cate that as much gold was produced in the third quarter of the 
 nineteenth century as in the preceding three centuries and a half 
 following the discovery of America. The result was to increase the 
 discrepancy between the mint ratio and the actual market ratio of 
 gold and silver, although the production of silver had also been
 
 230 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 greatly increased. Gold was brought to the mint for coinage in 
 enormous amounts, a condition that lasted even after 1861, when 
 paper currency began to be used almost exclusively as the medium 
 of exchange. 
 
 In a general revision of the coinage laws, enacted in 1873, the 
 silver dollar was dropped from the list of coins that could be manu- 
 factured at the mint. Although this action was almost unnoticed 
 at the time, a fictitious significance has, in subsequent years, been 
 attached to it. Silver was practically "demonetized," that is, its 
 free and unlimited coinage was actually prevented, by the estab- 
 lishment of the ratio of 1 6 to i in 1834. The act of 1873 gave legal 
 recognition to an existing fact. 
 
 But a sudden depreciation in the value of silver, which began at 
 about this time, brought the question of bimetallism again into the 
 foreground. Since the seventeenth century the relative values of 
 gold and silver had fluctuated only between relatively narrow mar- 
 gins, and in no year since the establishment of the United States 
 mint had the average annual value of an ounce of gold been less 
 than 15 or more than 16^ times the value of an ounce of silver. In 
 1875, however, the market ratio fell to 1 6.6 to i; by 1878 it was 
 18 to i; by 1886 it was 20.8 to i; and in 1894 it was 32.6 to i. 1 It 
 is evident that if the opportunity for the free and unlimited coinage 
 of silver at the ratio of 16 to i had still existed, there would have 
 been another sudden change in the actual standard of value. Gold 
 would have been undervalued by that ratio, and would have disap- 
 peared from circulation, and silver would have taken its place. It 
 was the realization of this fact, coupled with the knowledge that the 
 silver standard would mean a "cheaper dollar," that led to a popu- 
 lar agitation for the free and unlimited coinage of silver which 
 continued for more than twenty years. 
 
 The first tangible result of this agitation was a compromise meas- 
 
 1 The causes of this unprecedented decline in the relative value of one of the 
 precious metals were complex and intricate. The following may be mentioned, 
 however, as contributing circumstances: (i) Cessation of an extraordinary de- 
 mand for silver in India which had existed since 1850; (2) Stoppage of the unlim- 
 ited coinage of silver in several European countries; (3) Discovery of large silver 
 mines in the United States; (4) Increase in the value of gold, as evidenced by a 
 general decrease in the prices of commodities.
 
 MONEY 
 
 2 3 I 
 
 ure, the Bland-Allison Act, passed by Congress in 1878, which in- 
 stituted the limited coinage of silver dollars by authorizing the sec- 
 retary of the treasury to purchase at market prices not less than 
 $2,000,000 nor more than $4,000,000 worth of silver bullion per 
 month, and to coin it into dollars. The results of this enforced 
 coinage were satisfactory to neither party to the controversy. The 
 amount of silver coined was in excess of the demand for that bulky 
 kind of money, even though as much as possible was put into circu- 
 lation in the form of silver certificates, and although the govern- 
 ment tried to favor the distribution of silver by paying the expense 
 of transporting it to the localities where it was wanted. The move- 
 ment in favor of the unlimited coinage of silver continued to gain 
 in strength, however, its advocates claiming that "more silver," 
 rather than less, was needed. 
 
 A second compromise was effected in the Sherman act of 1890, 
 which provided for the increase in the amount of silver purchased 
 to 4,500,000 ounces each month, which was to be paid for in treas- 
 ury notes. These treasury notes were to be full legal tender, and 
 were redeemable in gold or silver coin at the discretion of the secre- 
 tary of the treasury. The silver was to be coined only so rapidly as 
 was found necessary for the redemption of the treasury notes. The 
 increase in the amount of silver purchased was a concession to the 
 advocates of the unlimited coinage of silver; the fact that the circu- 
 lating medium based immediately on these purchases was com- 
 posed of treasury notes, which were injected into circulation in 
 proportion to the market value of the silver purchased, was a con- 
 cession to their opponents. 
 
 The soundness of the principles embodied in the Sherman act 
 was soon tested by a period of financial and industrial depression. 
 Gold had to be exported to Europe in large quantities to settle an 
 adverse balance of trade, and the government found difficulty in 
 maintaining its own gold reserve, which was already seriously 
 threatened by a decline in customs receipts, accompanied by an in- 
 crease in federal expenditures. The gold reserve was at that time 
 simply the amount of gold in the treasury that was available for the 
 redemption of other forms of money, especially the United 
 States notes, or greenbacks, that had been first issued during the
 
 232 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Civil War, but which did not become actually redeemable in gold 
 until 1879. During this scarcity of gold the banks were able to 
 secure gold for their own reserves or for export by presenting 
 United States notes at the treasury for redemption in gold. Under 
 the law the notes had to be immediately reissued, and were used in 
 government payments, but no sooner was this done than they were 
 again returned by the banks for redemption in gold. 
 
 The workings of this "endless chain " by which gold was pumped 
 from the government treasury were aggravated by the fact that the 
 treasury notes authorized by the Sherman act were used for the 
 same purpose. Although they were payable either in gold or silver 
 coin, they were actually redeemed on demand in gold. This was 
 at the urgent insistence of President Cleveland, who believed, with 
 good reason, that a refusal to redeem them in gold would probably 
 have forced the silver standard upon us, by destroying the ex- 
 changeability of silver and gold and thus putting an end to their 
 parity, and that it would certainly have injured the credit of the 
 government and put it to a disadvantage in the bond sales that 
 were needed to replenish the gold reserve. Under the operations 
 of the Sherman act the government was virtually exchanging gold 
 coin for silver bullion at a time when gold was sorely needed and 
 when the value of the purchased silver was steadily depreciating. 
 
 The gold reserve sank from $190,000,000 in 1890 to $95,000,000 
 in 1893. I n J une f tne latter year the closing of the mints of India 
 to the unlimited coinage of silver gave an added impetus to the 
 downward movement of the value of that metal. These facts led 
 Congress, in a special session called in 1893 f r tnat purpose, to 
 order, though with obvious reluctance, that the purchase of silver 
 under the Sherman act should be stopped. 
 
 The agitation for the free and unlimited coinage of silver con- 
 tinued, however, and with increased vigor, and it was made the sole 
 issue in the presidential campaign of 1896. It was alleged that the 
 yet continuing industrial depression could be alleviated only by 
 "more money" and "cheaper money." It was claimed by many 
 intelligent people that the unlimited coinage of silver would not 
 drive gold from circulation, but would increase the value of silver 
 and decrease the value of gold until they met at a parity established
 
 MONEY 
 
 2 33 
 
 by the desired legal ratio of 16 to i. The most effective argument 
 of the protagonists of silver was found, however, in the admitted 
 fact that the value of gold, as shown by changes in the general price 
 level, had been increasing. All indications pointed toward a con- 
 tinued decrease in the annual production of gold, and a consequent 
 further increase in its value. This, it was argued, was a hardship 
 to those who had borrowed money on long time obligations, such 
 as mortgages, because they would be forced to repay in value or 
 purchasing power more than they had borrowed. 1 
 
 This agitation was, in fact, simply one of a series of cheap money 
 movements that have characterized the economic development of 
 the United States, and which have sprung from the fact that the 
 expense of opening up and developing new lands has necessitated 
 expenditures of capital in an amount far beyond the resources of 
 the actual settlers. Newly settled regions have usually been 
 debtor regions, and there is more than mere coincidence in the fact 
 that demands for cheap money have always been voiced most 
 loudly on the frontier. 2 This does not mean that a cheap money 
 movement is essentially dishonest; that it represents the conscious 
 attempts of debtors to escape the payment of their lawful debts. 
 The life and vigor in this movement for the unlimited coinage of 
 silver was put into it by men who saw the imputed value of their 
 assets sinking and the difficulty of paying their debts increasing in 
 a financial crisis for which they were not individually responsible. 
 Money funds were hard to get because individual credit, the founda- 
 tion of bank credit, was lacking. This scarcity of money funds 
 was confused, naturally, if erroneously, with the scarcity of 
 "money" in the sense of standard money, gold; and the remedy 
 was sought in an action that would give more and cheaper standard 
 money. 
 
 The defeat of the advocates of bimetallism in 1896 would prob- 
 ably not have stopped the agitation for the unlimited coinage of 
 silver, had it not been for the return of prosperous conditions, 
 
 1 This argument raises the problem of the standard of deferred payments, 
 which is to be considered in Chapter XVI. 
 
 2 Cf. C. J. Bullock, Essays in the Monetary History of the United States, 
 Part I.
 
 234 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 coupled with an enormous increase in the world's annual produc- 
 tion of gold, which has brought with it a general increase in prices. 
 
 The single gold standard was formally and definitely recognized 
 by law in 1900. All of the silver bullion purchased under the 
 Sherman act has been coined, and silver dollars sufficient in 
 amount to retire the treasury notes have been set aside for that 
 purpose. These treasury notes (which should not be confused 
 with United States notes, or greenbacks) are accordingly on sub- 
 stantially the same basis as silver certificates. Up to June 30, 1907, 
 their amount had been reduced from $156,000,000 to $6,000,000. 
 No silver dollars have been coined since 1904, and under the present 
 law no more can be coined until Congress authorizes the special 
 purchase of bullion for that purpose. 
 
 The Dominance of the Gold Standard. Within the last few 
 years gold has been accepted more generally and more definitely 
 than ever before as the standard money metal of the world. The 
 change from a silver, or bimetallic standard, to the gold standard 
 is often a difficult and expensive national undertaking, but it brings 
 the advantages of a more stable unit of value and of increased 
 facility in international exchange. In October, 1906, the silver 
 standard prevailed only in Bolivia, four of the countries of Central 
 America, China, Persia, and the Straits Settlements. 1 
 
 Government Paper Money. In metallic money of limited 
 coinage, there is, as we have seen, a considerable element of credit 
 value added to the actual bullion value of the coins. In paper 
 money the element of credit is alone present. Government paper 
 money is composed of instruments which bind the government to 
 pay, and usually to pay on demand, equivalent amounts of metallic 
 money, usually standard money. 
 
 Government paper money also differs from metallic money of 
 limited coinage in respect to the motives which give rise to and regu- 
 late its issue. Subsidiary coins are issued by the government in 
 response to the demand for a circulating medium for use in small 
 transactions and in making change. The public convenience is the 
 first consideration; the profit accruing to the government on such 
 coinage is a secondary thing. In issuing government paper money, 
 1 Report of the Director of the Mint, in Finance Report, 1907, p. 297.
 
 MONEY 
 
 2 35 
 
 however, fiscal motives have predominated. When hard pressed 
 to swell the government income to cover an increase in expenditures, 
 those responsible for the financial policies of a government have 
 sometimes deemed it advisable for the government to make use of 
 its own notes, promises to pay, in discharging its obligations. 
 
 These differ from government bonds, which are often issued in 
 similar circumstances, in that the bonds bear interest, are sold to 
 voluntary buyers, and are usually payable at a definite time in the 
 future, while government notes are usually non-interest bearing, 
 represent a forced, rather than a voluntary loan, and are usually, 
 in form at least, payable on demand, or in practice, at an indefinite 
 time in the future. They are, moreover, issued in convenient form 
 for monetary use, and are usually made legal tender, so that they 
 pass from hand to hand as a medium of exchange. The forced 
 loan which they represent is therefore shifted from those who first 
 receive the notes from the government in payment for goods or 
 services. 
 
 Colonial and Revolutionary Bills of Credit. Paper money 
 issues have frequently been used in the United States as a means of 
 meeting a fiscal emergency, especially those springing from the 
 extraordinary expenditures occasioned by wars. The expense of 
 sending troops to the Indian wars was one of the things that led 
 most of the American colonies to issue paper money. The history 
 of these colonial "bills of credit," as they were called, illustrate two 
 dangers that seem to be inseparable from the use of this financial 
 and monetary device. In the first place, it was very easy to suc- 
 cumb to the temptation of paying ordinary as well as extraordinary 
 expenditures in this easy way. Some of the colonies got entirely 
 out of the habit of taxing themselves to meet current public ex- 
 penses. The refusal to levy taxes was a prolific cause of disputes 
 between colonial assemblies and royal governors. 
 
 In the second place, because no money was raised for the pur- 
 pose, these bills of credit were not redeemed promptly. Their 
 value, as compared with metallic money, fell because people lost 
 confidence in their redeemability. As the currency depreciated, 
 it took continually larger issues of it to meet the government ex- 
 penditures, and each increase in the amount in circulation led to a
 
 236 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 further fall in value. After the currency had become practically 
 worthless, it was a common practice of the colonies to repudiate it 
 in whole or in part, and to start afresh with bills of a " new tenor." 
 Any attempt to restrict this reckless use of public credit was met 
 with determined resistance from the "cheap money" advocates of 
 that day. There were frequent complaints of the scarcity of money, 
 especially from the more newly settled districts. The greater the 
 quantity of money issued, the more insistent was the demand for 
 still further issues. In short, this colonial experience in itself gives 
 sufficient basis for the inference that from the monetary as well as 
 the fiscal point of view, the use of paper money easily degenerates 
 into a bad habit. 
 
 Again, in the Revolutionary War, paper money issues were made, 
 this time by the Continental Congress as well as by the individual 
 colonies. The Continental Congress was really driven to this action 
 by its lack of the power of levying taxes. Its bills became practi- 
 cally worthless, although every effort was made to maintain their 
 parity with metallic money by appeals to patriotic sentiment. 
 After the formation of the national government a few of them were 
 redeemed at one cent on the dollar. 
 
 It was our unfortunate colonial and revolutionary experience 
 with paper money which led to the insertion of the wise provision 
 in the federal Constitution which forbids the individual states to 
 issue bills of credit or to make anything but gold and silver legal 
 tender in payment of debts. 
 
 The Greenbacks. The federal government made no important 
 issues of paper money until the Civil War. 1 It was not generally 
 foreseen that that conflict would be so long continued and intense 
 as it was, and Congress consequently neglected to make adequate 
 provision for taxes that would help to meet the increased expendi- 
 tures and to sustain the government credit in the borrowing opera- 
 tions that were necessary. In 1861 the secretary of the treasury 
 was authorized to issue at his discretion $50,000,000 in "demand 
 
 'The federal government issued treasury notes in the war of 1812 and the 
 Mexican War, and during the panics of 1837 and 1857. Most of these issues were 
 interest bearing, however ; none of them were legal tender, and none of them got 
 into common use as media of exchange.
 
 MONEY 
 
 2 37 
 
 notes," which, although they were not legal tender, could be used 
 in all payments to the government. These were redeemed promptly 
 on demand until the end of the year, when the withdrawal of gold 
 from the banks by depositors for hoarding, and by the government 
 for its own uses, led first the banks and then the government to 
 suspend specie payments, that is, to refuse to pay their current 
 obligations in gold. 
 
 In 1 86 1, moved by the absolute necessity of providing some kind 
 of money for the federal treasury, Congress authorized the issue of 
 $i 50,000,000 in legal tender notes, 1 or greenbacks, as they came to 
 be called. It was hoped, moreover, that this increase in the circu- 
 lating medium would improve the market for government bonds 
 for which the greenbacks were at first made convertible at par. 
 This action was not taken without strenuous opposition on the part 
 of those who foresaw some of the disastrous consequences of large 
 paper money issues. But as in earlier American experience with 
 paper money, succeeding issues met with less and less resistance. 
 All together, greenbacks to the amount of $450,000,000 were 
 issued during the war. 
 
 It was the general expectation when the greenbacks were issued 
 that they would be retired as soon as possible after the conclusion 
 of the war. But when such action became possible, it was opposed 
 by many who thought that the reduction of the circulating medium 
 would decrease prices, impose additional burdens upon debtors, 
 injure business interests, reduce the public revenues, and hamper 
 the government in the refunding of its public debt. In 1866, how- 
 ever, Congress authorized the gradual retirement of the greenbacks, 
 but repealed the act in 1868. The amount in circulation in 1874 
 was $382,000,000, and in that year a bill requiring the definite in- 
 crease of the issue to $400,000,000 was prevented from becoming 
 law and thus establishing a dangerous precedent only by the veto 
 of President Grant. Some greenbacks were retired under the pro- 
 visions of an act of 1875, but in May, 1878, there were $346,681,000 
 outstanding, and as a law then enacted provides for their constant 
 reissue after being received or redeemed at the treasury, the amount 
 still stands at that figure. The part that they played in the financial 
 1 Including the "demand notes," which were now made legal tender.
 
 238 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 difficulties of 1890-1893, together with the history of the treasury 
 of the notes of 1890, has been described in connection with the dis- 
 cussion of bimetallism. 
 
 At present the greenbacks constitute a useful and acceptable part 
 of the stock of money. But if another financial crisis should 
 deplete the government treasury, they would very likely prove 
 again to be a source of difficulty. Their retirement is feasible under 
 present conditions, but would be most difficult to accomplish under 
 the very financial conditions under which they would be most dan- 
 gerous.. The currency act of 1900 provides for a gold reserve of 
 $i 50,000,000, to be held against them to insure their redeemability. 
 Jf the reserve falls below $100,000,000, the secretary of the treasury 
 is directed to replenish it from the proceeds of bond sales. Al- 
 though this gold reserve also constitutes part of the real security 
 behind our silver dollars, it could safely be diminished in amount 
 if the greenbacks were retired. 
 
 Economic Effects of the Greenbacks. The greenbacks are in 
 form promises to pay, but they are not promises to pay on demand, 
 nor at any specific time. During the period of the suspension of 
 specie payments they were not actually redeemable in gold, nor 
 was gold in general circulation as a medium of exchange except on 
 the Pacific coast. Gold was, however, in addition to its industrial 
 uses, employed as money in international trade, in the payment of 
 interest on government bonds, and for customs duties (for which 
 the greenbacks were not legally receivable). There was thus a 
 -constant demand for gold money, which was met by its sale as a 
 commodity in the New York market. The gold market was highly 
 speculative, the daily and even the hourly fluctuations in the price 
 of gold in greenbacks being considerable. Notwithstanding these 
 speculative features the prices paid for gold indicated very accu- 
 rately, in the long run, how much, in the expert judgment of market 
 specialists, the value of the greenbacks had depreciated. 
 
 Everything that was thought to affect the probability of the ulti- 
 mate redemption of the greenbacks in gold influenced their price. 
 Among these factors were the quantity of greenbacks issued, the 
 condition of the federal treasury, the military successes and re- 
 verses of the Union cause, and, in later years, the prospects for the
 
 MONEY 2 39 
 
 resumption of specie payments. Greenbacks reached a parity 
 with gold two weeks before the resumption of specie payments on 
 January i, 1879. A fact of special significance is that until July, 
 1863, the greenbacks were convertible at par into 6 per cent gold 
 bonds. These bonds formed an actual standard of value for the 
 greenbacks, and although themselves depreciated, exercised for 
 the time being a steadying influence upon their value. 
 
 As the common medium of exchange consisted almost entirely of 
 greenbacks l and of bank notes convertible only into greenbacks, 
 prices were measured in greenback "dollars" and naturally rose as 
 the gold value of the greenback depreciated. Reference to the 
 table on page 240 will show a rough correspondence between 
 changes in the general level of prices, expressed in greenbacks, and 
 changes in the value of gold, measured in greenbacks. But the 
 price of commodities rose relatively higher than did the price of 
 gold, and declined less rapidly. 2 Retail prices, in turn, declined 
 less rapidly than did wholesale prices. Wages advanced more 
 slowly than prices; maximum wages were not paid until 1872, 
 seven years after retail prices and eight years after wholesale prices 
 had reached their maximum. 
 
 That there was not a closer correspondence between the movement in gen- 
 eral prices and the changes in the gold value of the greenback was due to two 
 sets of influences: (i) Even if greenbacks had not been issued, and if prices 
 had been measured in gold, there would have been marked fluctuations in 
 prices, not only such as continually occur in normal years, but also those 
 due to such exceptional things as the withdrawal of a large number of men 
 from industry and agriculture to military service, the shifting of productive 
 effort in response to the enormous demand for military supplies, the period 
 of extraordinary business activity, of railway building, and of agricultural 
 and industrial expansion that followed the war, the reaction and financial 
 crisis in 1873, and the return of prosperous conditions in the last years of the 
 
 1 Subsidiary coins did not go out of circulation until 1862, when the value 
 of the greenback dropped below the value of the bullion in these coins. Postage 
 stamps and notes and tokens issued by cities and by business firms were for a 
 while used as small change. In 1863 the situation was helped by the issue 
 of fractional paper currency in denominations as low as three cents. 
 
 * The more detailed figures, of which the table given here is only a summary, 
 show that the prices of commodities also advanced more slowly than did the price 
 of gold. For an illuminating discussion of these price changes see MitchelL 
 Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard, Chap. V.
 
 240 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 TABLE I 
 PRICES AND WAGES IN THE GREENBACK PERIOD 1 
 
 YEAR 
 
 AVERAGE 
 ANNUAL PRICE 
 OF GOLD IN 
 GREENBACKS 
 
 JULY 
 WHOLESALE 
 PRICES ' 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL PRICES * 
 
 AVERAGE 
 WAGES 
 
 Wholesale 
 
 Retail 
 
 1860 
 
 
 100 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 1861 
 
 
 95 
 
 94 
 
 107 
 
 99 
 
 1862 
 
 "3-3 
 
 1 20 
 
 109 
 
 *3 r 
 
 104 
 
 1863 
 
 I45- 2 
 
 155 
 
 148 
 
 1 68 
 
 119 
 
 1864 
 
 203.3 
 
 236 
 
 225 
 
 215 
 
 142 
 
 1865 
 
 157-3 
 
 183 
 
 224 
 
 219 
 
 155 
 
 1866 
 
 140.9 
 
 191 
 
 203 
 
 208 
 
 164 
 
 1867 
 
 138.2 
 
 170 
 
 J 77 
 
 '93 
 
 167 
 
 1868 
 
 139-7 
 
 165 
 
 180 
 
 190 
 
 170 
 
 1869 
 
 133-0 
 
 158 
 
 172 
 
 177 
 
 179 
 
 1870 
 
 114.9 
 
 145 
 
 156 
 
 1 66 
 
 179 
 
 1871 
 
 111.7 
 
 137 
 
 144 
 
 5S 
 
 184 
 
 1872 
 
 112.4 
 
 139 
 
 138 
 
 151 
 
 185 
 
 1873 
 
 113.8 
 
 140 
 
 M3 
 
 148 
 
 183 
 
 1874 
 
 III. 2 
 
 138 
 
 144 
 
 M5 
 
 175 
 
 1875 
 
 114.9 
 
 129 
 
 134 
 
 140 
 
 163 
 
 1876 
 
 III.5 
 
 118 
 
 1 20 
 
 135 
 
 153 
 
 1877 
 
 104.8 
 
 114 
 
 117 
 
 !34 
 
 M3 
 
 1878 
 
 100.8 
 
 99 
 
 99 
 
 127 
 
 142 
 
 1879 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 98 
 
 93 
 
 123 
 
 139 
 
 1 Compiled from Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard, by Wesley C. 
 Mitchell. The figures in the price column are " index numbers," that is, they are obtained 
 by counting the price of each commodity in each year as a percentage of its price in 1860, and 
 then averaging the various relative prices thus obtained for each year. The figures in the 
 wage column are computed in a similar way. In the " price of gold " column parity between 
 greenbacks and gold is represented by 100. 
 
 92 commodities. 331 commodities. * For 78 establishments. 
 
 greenback period. 1 (2) The depreciation in the value of the greenback in 
 gold was measured quickly and accurately in the gold market, but the move- 
 ment of prices was hampered by habit, custom, existing contracts, local 
 influences, etc. We have seen in the discussion of value that retail prices 
 are less sensitive to changing market conditions than are wholesale prices. 
 
 1 This statement is subject to the limitation implied in the fact that general 
 commercial conditions were themselves caused in part by the influence of the 
 cheap and fluctuating medium of exchange.
 
 MONEY 
 
 2 4 I 
 
 Wages, in turn, are usually less mobile than retail prices. All these things 
 interacted. Wages, to give only one example, constitute an important part 
 of the expenses of producing commodities, and the sluggish movement of 
 wages kept the expenses of production from advancing, and, later, from 
 falling as rapidly as would otherwise have been the case, and must have had 
 a^corresponding effect on the prices charged for commodities. 
 
 Aside from these general changes, the minor fluctuations, the short- 
 time variations in prices, were unusually wide and numerous, 
 a fact which may be attributed to the uncertain value of the medium 
 of exchange. Such fluctuations were apt to upset all business cal- 
 culations; chance became more important and foresight less im- 
 portant as a factor in profits. Under such conditions an intense 
 and reckless spirit of speculation was bred, with unfortunate 
 effects on business morality as well as on economic conditions. 
 
 As a fiscal expedient, the greenbacks led to results as disastrous 
 as those which attended their use as money. The government was 
 forced to sell bonds for depreciated greenbacks, but in order to 
 maintain its credit it had to pay the interest and ultimately the prin- 
 cipal of these bonds in gold. Supplies for the army were paid for 
 in depreciated greenbacks, but these greenbacks had to be ulti- 
 mately redeemed in gold. It has been estimated that the use of 
 the greenbacks increased the cost of the Civil War by nearly 
 $600,000,000. 
 
 Fiat Money. After 1873 the advocates of cheap money were 
 not content with merely opposing any reduction in the quantity 
 of the greenbacks. They went so far as to urge that the amount of 
 paper money should be greatly increased, and that the use of 
 metallic money should be definitely and permanently abandoned. 
 Bank notes were also attacked because they were issued by "privi- 
 leged corporations." The question came to be an important politi- 
 cal issue, and in 1876 it brought about the organization of the 
 Greenback party, which figured in three presidential campaigns, 
 and which polled more than a million votes in the congressional 
 elections of 1878. In more recent years similar demands were 
 voiced by the Populist party. 
 
 The theory of money which formed the basis of the contention 
 of the members of the Greenback party is sometimes called the 
 "fiat money" theory. Those who held this theory of money saw
 
 242 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 no significance in the fact that the greenbacks were in form prom- 
 ises to pay and that they were generally regarded as only tem- 
 porarily irredeemable. In their view they were simply "dollars," 
 made such by the expressed will of the government. Nor did they 
 see any significance in the fact that during the seventeen years of 
 the suspension of specie payments over $500,000,000 in United 
 States gold coins issued from the mints. As a matter of fact the 
 fiat money advocates were misled by what some logicians have 
 called the "jingle fallacy." That the "dollar" of the ordinary 
 medium of exchange and the "dollar" as a standard unit of 
 value were different things did not occur to them. 
 
 If they had succeeded in eliminating the credit element in the 
 value of the paper currency by ceasing to print "promises to pay" 
 (as they actually proposed to do), and had instituted a new name 
 for the money unit, possibly (to reverse the spelling) "rallod," 
 they would surely have encountered difficulty in getting people 
 to accept pieces of printed paper, informing them that " This is a 
 rallod," as money. It is hard to see how "the supply of money as 
 compared with the demand for it," on which the fiat money advo- 
 cates counted to fix the value of their money units, would have 
 helped matters very much. Nor would the convertibility of fiat 
 money into interest-bearing bonds, which was suggested by some, 
 have given us a standard of value. For the bonds would have 
 been simple promises to pay a certain sum in fiat money units, with 
 interest at a certain rate, also in fiat money units. The difficulties 
 that would have been encountered in international trade would 
 alone have sufficed to make fiat money impossible. 
 
 Some writers have referred to the greenbacks as the "standard 
 of value" during the suspension of specie payments. As a matter 
 of fact gold, under the operations of unlimited coinage, was the ulti- 
 mate standard, and the standard dollar was the gold dollar. The 
 value of the greenback dollar, in which prices were measured, was 
 the value of the gold dollar, discounted according to the outlook for 
 the ultimate redemption of the greenbacks in gold. The green- 
 backs were at most only a "secondary standard" of value. 
 
 (For Questions and References, see the following chapter.)
 
 CHAPTER XV 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 Credit Transactions. Thus far, in our discussion of money, we 
 have failed to take account of the fact that the greater part of ex- 
 changes are credit transactions, which do not directly or immedi- 
 ately involve the use of money (in the sense of generally acceptable 
 money instruments). A credit transaction is a transfer of goods, 
 services, or money, for a future equivalent. In a "cash" transac- 
 tion there are only two elements, the goods sold and the money 
 paid for them. But in a credit transaction a third element time 
 is added. The introduction of this third element leads to ex- 
 ceedingly important results. In the first place it makes possible an 
 enormous number of exchanges in which the buyer is either unable 
 or disinclined to render a present equivalent. In the second place 
 it obviates, to a very large extent, the necessity of using money. 
 
 Suppose, for example, that A and B are the only inhabitants of 
 an isolated community. Three ways of making exchanges are 
 open to them. They can use a system of direct exchange or 
 barter, which will prevent A from getting goods from B unless he 
 has some equivalent which he is willing to give up and which B 
 is willing to accept. Or, they may use one commodity as money, 
 in which case the purchasing power of either A or B at any given 
 time will be governed by the amount of that particular commodity 
 that he possesses, rather than by the total amount of all his posses- 
 sions. But by combining a system of credit with their use of 
 money, they will be able to make transfers freely, for in an occa- 
 sional balancing of accounts most of the payments due each other 
 will cancel, leaving only a relatively small amount to be paid in 
 money. 
 
 Something very much like this third process is continually going 
 on in contemporary economic life. The process is more complex, 
 
 243
 
 244 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 however, because A actually sells things to one person or group of 
 persons, and buys them from other persons. And it is very likely 
 that these two groups, the sellers and the buyers in A's transactions, 
 have no direct business transactions with each other in which their 
 respective claims against A and debts to A can be canceled. If, 
 however, we take all buyers and all sellers into account, and if we 
 could push our analysis of the complex network of credit relations 
 far enough, we would find points of contact between A's credits 
 and his debts. That is, if A gives a promissory note in exchange 
 for a purchased good, this promissory note might be passed on 
 from hand to hand until it got into the possession of some one who 
 is indebted to A, if the path it should take were known. The 
 difficulty is that the path is not known. The institution of banking, 
 however, provides clearing centers, where credits and debts are 
 balanced against each other and canceled. 
 
 A, for example, has a "deposit" in a local bank, which means 
 that he has the right to demand payments from it at any time up to 
 the amount of his deposit. He usually makes a payment to B, 
 not by a promissory note, but by a check, an instrument order- 
 ing the bank to pay B the specified amount. This check will be 
 presented for payment by B at a bank where he has a deposit, but 
 the "payment" will usually be made by adding the amount of the 
 check to B's deposit. If it is the bank where A also has his deposit, 
 the transaction is settled by the simple process of debiting A's de- 
 posit and crediting B's. If it is another bank in the same town, 
 and if the town is a small one, the check will enter into the daily 
 exchange by the two banks of such claims against each other, the 
 daily balance in favor of either bank being usually settled in money. 
 
 In the larger cities a further economy in the use of money is 
 achieved by means of the clearing house, to which a representative 
 of each bank brings daily all of the checks drawn against other 
 local banks which it has received since the last "clearing." At 
 the clearing house the checks are turned over to the representatives 
 of the banks against which they are drawn, but the balances are not 
 settled between the individual banks. Instead, a balance is struck 
 between the total sum of each bank's claims against other banks 
 and the total claims of other banks against it. Each bank then
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 245 
 
 pays to the clearing house, usually in money, or receives from it, 
 as the case may be, the amount of balance due to it or from it. 
 This system achieves a great economy of both time and money. 1 
 
 If the banks in which A and B keep their deposits are in different 
 towns, A's check will probably be sent by B's bank to a bank in a 
 neighboring large city, in which B's bank has its own deposit ac- 
 count. If A's bank is also in the territory tributary to this same 
 city, the check may be sent by the city bank directly to A's bank 
 for collection, or to its own correspondent bank in the same town. 
 If A's bank is in another part of the country, the check will be sent 
 to a bank located in a large city in that region, which will attend 
 to its collection. 2 Thus a check drawn on a local bank in California, 
 deposited in a local bank in Illinois, will very likely be collected via 
 Chicago and San Francisco. The balances of credits and debits 
 which are thus created between city and country banks are settled 
 to a very large extent by means of crediting and debiting deposit 
 accounts in city banks, thus obviating by that much the necessity 
 for frequent shipments of money. In general, we have in the 
 United States a continuous balancing and cancellation of debts and 
 credits, first, in each locality; second, between each important city 
 and its tributary territory, and, third, between the different impor- 
 tant cities. Much the same process is characteristic of international 
 exchange, but that is a topic which will be treated in another 
 chapter. 
 
 1 Over $95,300,000,000 in checks and drafts passed through the New York 
 Clearing House in the year ending September i, 1907. The money balances 
 paid amounted to $3,800,000,000, or only 4 per cent of the total clearings. The 
 average cash payments required during the last fifty-four years have amounted 
 to 4.64 per cent of the clearings. In times of financial stringency clearing houses 
 sometimes allow the payment of balances in "clearing house certificates," issued 
 to individual banks upon the basis of approved securities deposited with the 
 clearing house. In some cases the banks have temporarily put such certificates 
 into general circulation as an emergency currency. 
 
 2 The London Clearing House clears for all England in a very simple and 
 efficient way. A country bank sends its daily receipts of checks on banks in other 
 towns to the London bank in which it keeps a deposit. In a daily "country clear- 
 ing" these checks are distributed to the London banks with which the banks on 
 which the checks are drawn keep accounts. The mere territorial extent of the 
 United States makes such a scheme unworkable here. Various proposals have 
 been made, however, for central clearing houses that will make clearances for 
 limited districts.
 
 246 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Personal Credit. If a man does not hoard money on the one 
 hand, or fail to pay his debts on the other hand, his expenditures 
 (including investments) are bound to be, in the long run, approxi- 
 mately equal to his income. But for a business man a continuous 
 equality of income and expenditure is impossible. At some times 
 his deposit account will be built up more rapidly than he checks it 
 out; at other times his need for means of making payments will 
 outrun his receipts. If, for example, he is a contractor, whose ex- 
 penses of production are fairly constant, but whose product is paid 
 for only when completed, or a merchant, who replenishes his stock 
 of goods twice a year but whose sales are distributed throughout 
 the year, or a farmer who must pay his harvest expenses before he 
 sells his crops, he may find it necessary to utilize his credit. Now, 
 his personal credit, his power of purchasing things without immedi- 
 ate payment, will depend to some extent on his personal ability and 
 integrity. But, nevertheless, the fundamental measure of his 
 credit" will be the amount of his realizable wealth. This, however, 
 is apt to consist largely of property that is not "for sale," his 
 stock of consumption goods and his income yielding land or 
 capital. 
 
 These things do not have to be sold in order to convert them into 
 means of payment. To meet a temporary need they may be made 
 the basis of credit, through the process of hypothecation, a name 
 which means the conditional transfer of property rights. The 
 hypothecation may be definite and formal, as when a mortgage is 
 given on specific items of property or when valuable credit instru- 
 ments of various sorts (such as government or corporation bonds, 
 bills of lading, warehouse receipts, etc.) are put into the actual pos- 
 session of the creditor as "collateral security " ; or it may be simply 
 implied, as in the case of an "unsecured" personal note, for practi- 
 cally all of the property of a borrower, over and above the items 
 specifically hypothecated for certain debts is, in legal fact, hypothe- 
 cated for his remaining debts. It is important to note, too, that 
 future values, rather than present values, constitute the basis of 
 present credit. The lender's interest is in the question of the ade- 
 quacy of the value of the security at the time when payment be- 
 comes due. Present values being equal, a borrower can secure a
 
 CREDIT A.\:> BAXKIXO 
 
 247 
 
 larger amount of credit when market conditions are improving 
 than when they are declining. 
 
 A man's probable future income and the probable future value 
 of his property, then, constitute the real measure and foundation 
 of his individual credit. His individual credit, however, is of very 
 little use to him as a means of payment. Some difficulties in the 
 way of using individual notes as media of exchange have already 
 been suggested. 1 There is another difficulty in the fact that his 
 personal notes will not be willingly accepted by others in lieu of 
 money payments unless they know him, the value of his property 
 and the extent to which it is already hypothecated. Moreover, 
 these same difficulties stand in the way of such notes being passed 
 from hand to hand through successive indorsements. 
 
 Bank Credit. In order to make it readily available as a medium 
 of exchange, personal credit has to be transformed into bank credit. 
 Instead of using his own note as a medium of exchange, a business 
 man will normally have it "discounted" by his banker. If the 
 note is for sixty days, for example, the business man yields the right 
 to demand a specific amount of money from him in sixty days, in 
 exchange for a deposit credit, the right to receive on demand the 
 same amount of money less the discount. 2 The business man adds 
 the note to his liabilities and a deposit to his assets. The bank adds 
 the note to its assets and the deposit to its liabilities. 
 
 Having converted his personal credit into a bank deposit, the 
 business man can now use it as a means of payment through the 
 checking system that has been described. Ordinary commercial 
 banking consists, in large part, of this purchase of personal credit 
 
 1 It is true, of course, that business men often accept their customers' notes in 
 payment of accounts, or as an equivalent for goods purchased. These notes, 
 however, do not usually pass any farther as a medium of exchange, but are in- 
 dorsed by the business man and presented to a bank for discount. Such notes, 
 usually known as "trade paper," constitute a large part of the securities of many 
 commercial banks. 
 
 2 Discount is simply one form of interest. Banker's discount differs from 
 ordinary interest in that it is computed as a certain per cent of the total amount 
 that is repaid, while ordinary interest is computed as a per cent of the amount that 
 is loaned. Discount is deducted from the principal of the loan in advance; in- 
 terest is paid at the maturity of the loan or (on long time loans) at stated intervals. 
 On demand or "call" loans and on time loans on collateral security "interest" 
 rather than "discount" is charged.
 
 248 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 and sale of banking credit. The bank builds up assets in the form 
 of loans and discounts at the same time that it builds up its obliga- 
 tions in the form of deposits. 
 
 The security behind the deposits in any bank consists of : (i) loans 
 and discounts, which in turn rest back upon personal credit or upon 
 specifically hypothecated property (as in the case of loans on col- 
 lateral security); (2) bonds, mortgages, and other securities owned 
 by the bank, which, if necessary, may be sold for the benefit of the 
 depositors, unless specifically pledged as security for bank note 
 issues; (3) the bank's own deposits in other banks, together 
 with the checks or similar claims against other banks that are in 
 its possession; (4) its other property (building, fixtures, etc.); 
 (5) (in national banks and some state banks) the personal liability 
 of the bank's stockholders; 1 (6) its stock of money. 
 
 But that these assets should suffice to cover the deposit liabilities 
 of a bank is not in itself sufficient to maintain its solvency. Much 
 depends upon the character of the assets, the amount of money 
 included in them, and the ease and quickness with which other 
 parts of the assets can be converted into money. Each deposit 
 account is an obligation of the bank to pay in actual money if it is 
 demanded. The depositor cannot use checks for all kinds of pay- 
 ments, but will often have to draw on his deposit account for 
 money. Even when payments are made by checks, those who re- 
 ceive them will often prefer to cash them rather than to deposit 
 them. Moreover, the process of the cancelation of credit obliga- 
 tions is, as we have seen, not altogether perfect. Balances arise 
 between individual banks in the same city, between city and 
 country, and between different cities that very often have to be 
 settled in money. 
 
 A bank accordingly has to keep enough actual cash on hand to 
 enable it to meet any demands that may be made upon it for money. 
 
 1 Even in case some of the bank's loans or securities prove worthless there 
 is a margin of safety for the depositors in the fact that some of the assets of the 
 bank represent the original investments of the bank's stockholders ("capital") 
 or profits which they have put back into the business ("surplus"), and on such 
 assets the depositors have the first claim. Moreover, in national banks and some 
 state banks the stockholders are personally liable up to an amount equal to the 
 par value of their holdings.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 249 
 
 As deposits constitute the most important cash obligations of a 
 bank, the size of this money reserve, as it is called, is normally fixed 
 for safety's sake at a certain per cent of the amount of the deposits. 
 This proportion varies according to the location of a bank and the 
 nature of its business. In practice it varies in different commercial 
 banks from as low as 5 per cent to as high as 35 per cent of the 
 deposits. 
 
 If its reserve increases, a bank is at liberty to increase its deposits 
 by extending its loans and discounts, attracting these, possibly, by 
 lowering the discount rate. If the reserve is decreasing, the bank 
 must, for safety, contract its deposits by restricting its loans and 
 discounts, or by taking measures (such as the sale of securities for 
 money) that will replenish the reserve. 1 In order that the ratio of 
 reserve to deposits may be maintained near the point where the 
 right balance is struck between profitableness on the one hand and 
 safety on the other hand, it is necessary that the bank's assets should 
 be as fluid as possible. This is best accomplished by confining 
 most of the loans or discounts to notes or bills of exchange that are 
 payable in thirty, sixty, or ninety days, or, at most, in four or six 
 months, so that a constant flow of maturing obligations makes it 
 possible for a bank to expand or contract its loans and discounts, 
 and hence its deposits, as seems most advisable. 
 
 There is in the larger cities of the United States, especially in 
 New York, a growing use of bank loans payable on demand. This 
 enables the banks to keep their outstanding loans much closer to the 
 maximum allowed by the state of their reserves than would other- 
 wise be the case, but the practice has, as we shall see presently, 
 other effects that are not so desirable. 
 
 By the "money market" is usually meant the market for ex- 
 changeable purchasing power in the form of loanable funds ; that is, 
 in reality, the bank credit market. The amount of bank credit 
 available, the freedom with which banks will make loans on certain 
 
 1 Some banks maintain a "bond reserve" of high grade securities that may be 
 sold to enable the bank to meet an extraordinary demand for money or to enable 
 it to extend its loans and discounts when necessary. Such investments are 
 normally made by commercial banks when the demand for loans does not absorb 
 the funds at the bank's disposal, that is, when money reserves are unprofitably 
 large.
 
 250 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 kinds of securities, and the interest and discount rates charged for 
 bank credit are among the things that make up what is called "the 
 state of the money market." But it should be clear to the reader 
 that the state of the money market depends, primarily, on two things: 
 first, the amount and nature of the personal credit that can be converted 
 into bank credit, and second, the amount of money in the bank reserves. 
 
 Bank Notes. There is one way, however, in which banks can 
 meet some of the demand for money without drawing on their re- 
 serves and thus reducing their power of extending credit. This is 
 by the issue of bank notes, which are simply the promises of banks 
 to pay money on demand, issued in convenient and familiar form 
 for use as paper money. These notes are paid as money to cus- 
 tomers of a bank who want the proceeds of their borrowings in cash, 
 and to depositors and to holders of checks who prefer money to 
 deposit credit. Bank notes pass readily from hand to hand as 
 money, and at the present time constitute an important part of the 
 circulating medium in most countries. 
 
 Bank notes are like deposits in that both are demand liabilities 
 of banks. Bank notes, however, circulate among persons who have 
 no means of informing themselves as to the solvency of the banks 
 issuing them. The holders of bank notes are accordingly usually 
 given special protection by laws which regulate the conditions of 
 their issue and redemption. 
 
 State Banks of Issue. Before the Civil War the actual circu- 
 lating medium of the United States consisted in very large part of 
 notes issued by banks operating under state laws. The notes 
 issued by some of these banks were as "good as gold" because the 
 banks redeemed them promptly in gold, a fact which was due in 
 some cases to wise and rigid state regulation of banking, and in 
 other cases, fewer in number, to conservative use of the too exten- 
 sive privileges granted by lax state laws. But the notes of other 
 banks were depreciated and in many cases were absolutely worth- 
 less. 
 
 Public ignorance of the real nature of banking gave rise to the 
 supposition that wealth could be mysteriously manufactured by 
 means of a bank charter and a printing press (the fiat money theory 
 applied to bank notes). This and the ever recurring demand for
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 25! 
 
 cheap money were responsible for the situation. Prohibited by the 
 Constitution from issuing their own bills of credit, many of the states, 
 especially in the South and West, responded to the clamor for cheap 
 money by making it possible for their citizens to organize "banks" 
 and issue their own bills of credit, imposing few or no requirements 
 as to the actual investment of capital, the accumulation of assets, 
 or the restriction of note issue. 1 In the panics of 1814, 1837, and 
 1857 but few banks maintained specie payments. Even so late as 
 1860, although the hard lessons of experience had brought some 
 improvements, especially in the older states, the bank note circula- 
 tion was of decidedly varying quality. "Bank note reporters" 
 and "counterfeit detectors" had to be issued periodically in order 
 to give to business men the latest quotations and information relat- 
 ing to the depreciated currency they had to receive in the ordinary 
 course of business. After 1861 the" suspension of specie payments 
 led to a general depreciation of bank notes as compared with gold 
 because most of them were thereafter redeemable only in green- 
 backs. 
 
 The National Banking System. The successful state banking 
 system of New York was the model after which Congress, following 
 the recommendations of Secretary Chase, patterned the national 
 banking system which it established in 1863. The primary, 
 although not the only, motive that led to this action was the desire 
 to provide an artificial market for government bonds, which at the 
 time were a drug on the market. National banks were required to 
 use government bonds as the assets behind note issues, and further- 
 more, the national banks were, in 1866, given a monopoly of the 
 note issue privilege by the imposition of a prohibitive tax of 10 
 per cent per annum upon the note issues of state banks. 
 
 The details of the national banking law have been amended from 
 time to time, but the general principles of the regulation of the note 
 issue remained unchanged until Congress passed the Aldrich act in 
 1908. As the law has stood since 1900, national banks may not be 
 organized unless the stockholders contribute a minimum capital, 
 
 1 Some states circumvented the constitutional prohibition mentioned by es- 
 tablishing their own banks for the manufacture of paper money. The Bank of 
 Kentucky was the most famous of these.
 
 252 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 varying from $25,000 for places of less than 3000 population to 
 $200,000 for places of more than 50,000 population. Three limita- 
 tions are put on the ordinary issue of circulating notes: (i) They 
 must not exceed in amount the capital stock of the bank. (2) United 
 States government bonds have to be purchased by the bank in 
 amount sufficient to equal, dollar for dollar, the quantity of the 
 notes issued, and these bonds have to be deposited with the treas- 
 urer of the United States as security for the redemption of the notes. 
 (3) Each bank must maintain in the United States treasury a re- 
 demption fund in "lawful money" equal to 5 per cent of its note 
 issue. As this last requirement indicates, bank notes are redeem- 
 able at the federal treasury. They may also be used in all pay- 
 ments to the government except customs duties, although they are 
 not legal tender. 
 
 The Reserve System. While the note holder is thus protected 
 by a special kind of security set aside for the purpose, the depositor 
 in a national bank is protected only by its general assets. These, 
 however, are regulated to some extent by the federal government. 
 There are restrictions, for example, intended to prevent the bank 
 from tying up its funds in long-time investments, from lending too 
 much to one person or firm, or to directors or officers of the banks. 
 Five times a year national banks have to furnish full statements of 
 their condition to the comptroller of the currency at Washington. 
 Each bank is also examined twice a year, without notice, by federal 
 bank examiners. 
 
 But the most important requirement relates to the money re- 
 serves that must be held by national banks. Banks in "central 
 reserve cities " (which at present are New York, Chicago, and St. 
 Louis) are required to maintain a "lawful money reserve" 1 
 equal to at least 25 per cent of their deposits. Banks in other 
 "reserve cities" (including at present about forty cities) are also 
 required to maintain 25 per cent reserves, but their deposits 
 in the national banks of the central reserve cities may be 
 counted for one half of this amount. In all other places the banks 
 are required to hold a 15 per cent reserve, three fifths of which 
 
 1 Including all kinds of United States money except subsidiary silver, minor 
 coins, and national bank notes.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 2 53 
 
 may consist of deposit accounts in banks in central reserve cities 
 or other reserve cities. In all cases the funds kept by the banks 
 with the United States treasurer for the redemption of their notes 
 are counted as part of their legal reserves. 
 
 The New York Money Market. Under the operations of this 
 system the cash reserves of the national banks are centered in New 
 York. This appears clearly in Table I, which shows that on the 
 date specified more than a third of the cash reserves of the 6544 
 
 TABLE I 
 DEPOSITS AND RESERVES OF NATIONAL BANKS: AUGUST 22, 1907' 
 
 LOCATION 
 
 No. OF 
 BANKS 
 
 DEPOSITS ' 
 
 RESEKVE 
 
 CLASSIFICATION OF RESERVE 
 
 Amount ' 
 
 Ratios J 
 
 Lawful 
 money in 
 bank ' 
 
 Due from 
 reserve 
 agents 
 
 Redemp- 
 tion fund' 
 
 New York 
 
 38 
 M 
 8 
 306 
 6178 
 
 825-7 
 262.9 
 116.8 
 
 1423-4 
 2627.2 
 
 221.3 
 
 66.6 
 27.6 
 362.3 
 
 443-5 
 
 26.8 
 
 25-3 
 23.6 
 
 25-5 
 16.9 
 
 218.8 
 66.1 
 26.8 
 190.3 
 199.6 
 
 
 2.6 
 
 0-5 
 0.7 
 
 6-3 
 17.2 
 
 Chicago 
 
 
 St. Louis 
 
 165-7 
 226.7 
 
 Other reserve cities 
 Country banks . . 
 
 Total 
 
 6544 
 
 5256-1 
 
 1121.4 
 
 21-3 
 
 701.6 
 
 392-4 
 
 27-3 
 
 
 1 Compiled from Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1007, pp. 222-224. 
 ' Millions of dollars. Per cent. 
 
 national banks in the United States were in the vaults of thirty- 
 eight New York banks. 1 These figures do not, however, convey 
 an adequate idea of the national importance of the New York bank 
 reserves. New York is the great wholesale market for foreign ex- 
 change, the chief center of gold movements to and from Europe, 
 the principal importing and exporting center for commodities, 
 in short, the chief market place of the continent and the focus of 
 financial operations. All state banks, private banks, and trust 
 companies of importance find it to their advantage to maintain 
 deposit accounts in New York, both for their own use, and in order 
 
 1 The bulk of the deposits of out of town banks were in from twelve to twenty 
 banks which make a specialty of this kind of business.
 
 254 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 that they may supply New York exchange to their customers. 
 Even the deposit accounts of national banks in New York are in 
 the aggregate considerably larger than the amount they are allowed 
 to count as part of their reserves. 
 
 All together the deposits of other banks constituted more than 
 half of the $825,700,000 of deposits in New York national banks 
 in August, 1907. Moreover, something very much like the reserve 
 system obtains among other than national banks, the banks in 
 smaller places keeping deposits in national or other banks in larger 
 cities, which in turn keep deposits in New York. The trust com- 
 panies, and some of the state banks l keep in general very much 
 smaller reserves in their own vaults than are required of national 
 banks, a fact which makes the strain on the New York bank 
 reserves all the greater. Recent legislation in New York has 
 raised the reserve requirements of state banks and trust com- 
 panies in that state. 
 
 Like an inverted pyramid upon its apex, the great structure of 
 bank credit in the United States rests, in large measure, upon the 
 money reserves of the New York banks. Every important change 
 in the demand for money or credit in any part of the country has an 
 effect on the New York money market; similarly, every important 
 disturbance in the New York money market affects financial con- 
 ditions throughout the country. 
 
 The central reserve system leads to a great economy in the use 
 of money, and it seems to be a natural and necessary feature of 
 modern banking, for something like it is found in all of the leading 
 commercial nations, although, in Europe, the central reserves 
 are kept in one great bank in each country. Some dangers seem 
 to attend its use in the United States, but these are in large measure 
 attributable to other features of our banking system, chief among 
 which are the dominance of speculative influences in the New York 
 money market, the independent treasury system, and the lack of 
 elasticity in our bank note issues. 
 
 1 Savings banks keep reserves that average for the United States only four 
 fifths of one per cent of their deposits. On account of the nature of their busi- 
 ness, which is not banking in the commercial sense, they are a negligible factor 
 in this connection.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 2 55 
 
 Speculation and the New York Money Market. As Table II 
 shows, a large and increasing proportion of the loans of New York 
 banks are not based on "commercial paper " ; that is, on the notes 
 and bills of exchange that arise in the ordinary course of business, 
 but are either time loans on collateral security or demand loans, 
 nearly all of which are secured by collateral. Most of these col- 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 LOANS AND DISCOUNTS OF NEW YORK NATIONAL BANKS ON SPECIFIED 
 
 DATES l 
 
 (In millions of dollars.) 
 
 CHARACTER OP LOAN 
 
 1890 
 
 1896 
 
 1901 
 
 IOO6 
 
 On demand 
 
 IO2 
 
 no 
 
 27O 
 
 1O 1 
 
 On time, with collateral security 
 
 A-I 
 
 60 
 
 I 2O 
 
 IJQ 
 
 On time, secured by commercial paper 
 
 152 
 
 144. 
 
 2O T, 
 
 240 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Compiled from Reports of the Comptroller of the Currency. 
 
 lateral securities are the stocks and bonds of corporations, and the 
 loans, especially the demand or "call" loans, are used for the 
 greater part in financing speculation in such securities. This sys- 
 tem is partly responsible for the excessive and useless expansion of 
 speculation over and above the amount that is necessary to secure 
 the best results for the economic interests of the country. Here 
 we are concerned, however, with its effects on the money market. 
 The supply of call loans depends primarily on the amount of the 
 surplus reserves of New York banks; that is, the excess of the re- 
 serves over and above the legal minimum of 25 per cent of 
 the amount of the deposits. If the weekly statement of the clearing 
 house banks l shows a relatively large surplus reserve, this means 
 that the banks can safely expand their loans, the knowledge of 
 which fact has a stimulating effect on speculation. If, however, 
 the surplus reserve is low, the banks are bound to restrict their 
 loans of all kinds and to "call" some of their demand loans. 
 
 1 Some of the banks in the clearing house are state banks, but by the rules of 
 the clearing house these were required to maintain the same reserve as national 
 banks even before recent legislative enactments.
 
 256 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 When the reserve is below the legal limit demand loans have to be 
 called in large quantities in order to enable the banks to meet press- 
 ing demands for credit on the part of their regular customers. 1 
 The precipitate calling of demand loans by some banks simply in- 
 creases the demand for credit at other banks, which in turn have to 
 curtail their loans. Such a condition of the money market leads 
 to a depression in the price of speculative securities, which is in- 
 creased by the forced sales of securities in order to obtain the money 
 funds that had previously been lent on them; the fall in the price 
 of securities leads brokers to demand more "margins" from the 
 customers for whom they have bought securities, and it leads the 
 banks to demand more securities as collateral for their outstanding 
 loans. Under such conditions the interest rate on call loans some- 
 times goes as high as 125 per cent, or even higher. 2 
 
 If the ruling prices of speculative securities have been higher than 
 industrial conditions would warrant, such a disturbance of the 
 money market is apt to be long continued, and might easily develop 
 into a general financial crisis. The call loan market is essentially 
 
 1 The rigidity of the New York bank reserves is itself an element of danger to 
 the money market. The Bank of England protects its reserves when they are 
 threatened by the simple process of raising its discount rate. The effect of this 
 is to restrict the loans of other banks as well as of the Bank of England to the 
 more necessitous borrowers. Under our national banking law limiting the rate 
 of interest, further loans have to be stopped absolutely when the reserve goes below 
 the legal minimum. The New York bank reserve is accordingly a real reserve 
 only in the sense that it makes it possible for the banks to meet extraordinary 
 demands for ready cash. So far as the extension of credit is concerned, it is not 
 a reserve, but a dead line. In practice the law is not rigidly observed, a warning 
 from the comptroller of the currency being the only penalty exacted for a tem- 
 porary deficit in the reserves. Nevertheless the reserve does not often fall more 
 than one or two points below the legal minimum. The sudden curtailment of 
 loans which the rigidity of the reserve entails is one of the things that tends to 
 convert an incipient panic into a real panic. 
 
 3 That is, the rate on what may be called marginal call loans, effected at the 
 stock exchange by bankers' agents, or by individuals or corporations. Many 
 banks continue to make call loans to their regular customers at such times at 
 rates not exceeding 6 per cent. Under normal conditions the rate on call loans 
 is lower than the rate on time loans. For the period 1901-1906 the bank rate 
 on call loans averaged 3.3 per cent as against an average rate of about 4.5 per cent 
 on time loans. Excessive variability is the chief characteristic of the call loan 
 rate. Cf. W. A. Scott, "Rates on the New York Money Market," Journal oj 
 Political Economy, Vol. XVI, pp. 273-298.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 2 57 
 
 speculative, and it is unfortunate that the condition of the supply 
 of credit for the normal commercial needs of the country should be 
 periodically unsettled on account of this fact. In no other great 
 money center of the world do call loans occupy the important place 
 that they do in New York. 1 
 
 The Independent Treasury System. The United States govern- 
 ment is to a very large extent its own banker. It keeps its own 
 money in its own strong boxes, quite after the fashion of a mediaeval 
 monarch. The strong boxes in this case are, however, the vaults 
 of the treasury in Washington and of nine sub-treasuries located 
 in important cities. Apart from the fact that the government 
 revenue and the government expenditures are naturally not dis- 
 tributed evenly throughout the year, the government has the further 
 difficulty that a close balance of revenues and expenditures for any 
 given year must be wholly accidental. Even if the federal budget 
 were carefully and scientifically constructed, as it is not, the public 
 revenues would be liable to uncertain fluctuations, a result in 
 part of the importance of customs receipts among them. The gov- 
 ernment, furthermore, receives most of its income in money, not 
 in bank credit instruments. When a surplus accumulates in the 
 government treasury, that much money is taken out of circulation, 
 which reduces the bank reserves, and contracts the amount of bank 
 credit available. 
 
 The government is permitted, however, by the national bank act 
 of 1863 to deposit money in selected national banks. Some secre- 
 taries of the treasury have made little use of this privilege, but in 
 recent years such deposits have become more common. 
 
 Until 1902 banks had always been required to deposit government bonds 
 with the federal treasury as security for federal deposits, but in that year and 
 again in 1906 Secretary Shaw offered to accept approved state and munici- 
 pal bonds in lieu of a certain amount of government bonds, on condition 
 that the latter should be immediately used as security for increased note 
 issues. In 1897 only 168 banks were government depositories. In 1907 
 
 1 The control of groups of powerful banks by great chains of "financial Inter- 
 ests" is another anomalous condition of the New York money market. For 
 an account and criticism of this situation as it existed in 1903, see C. J. Bullock, 
 "The Concentration of Banking Interests in the United States," Atlantic 
 Monthly, Vol. 92, pp. 182-192. 
 s
 
 258 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 there were 1255, which held on June 20 of that year $167,000,000 out of a 
 total treasury balance of $422,000,000. Part of this increase is attributable 
 to the effect of a law enacted in 1907 allowing custom receipts to be deposited 
 in banks. Previously to this deposits could only be made from the proceeds 
 of internal revenue duties and miscellaneous receipts. The Aldrich act of 
 1908 provided for the payment of one per cent interest on all government 
 deposits except the active checking accounts. 
 
 The government has, on several occasions, come to the rescue of the banks 
 by cash purchases of its own bonds. The decline in the market price of 
 government bonds in periods of financial stringency makes these purchases 
 relatively advantageous to the government. The periodic shifting of govern- 
 ment deposits to localities where money is most needed, the temporary 
 deposit of gold in New York banks equal in amount to their engagements of 
 gold for transportation from Europe, and even the arbitrary withdrawal 
 of government money from the banks when it was "not needed," in order 
 that it might not be made the basis of speculative activities but kept till the 
 time when it "was needed," * have been recent developments in the relation 
 of the treasury to the money market. 
 
 In favor of this system as at present developed it may be said that a sur- 
 plus in the government treasury constitutes a real cash reserve, the wise use 
 of which by the secretary of the treasury may possibly avert a serious crisis. 
 But there are dangers in intrusting so much financial power to one man. 
 If used without discretion it is bound to do more harm than good. More- 
 over, some of the recent treasury operations have not been free from the 
 suspicion of favoritism to certain banks. It is to be feared, too, that the 
 knowledge that the government surplus will, in time of necessity, be put at 
 their disposal, will tend to encourage unsound banking by relieving the 
 banks of the proper responsibility for the maintenance of their own reserves. 
 All in all it seems probable that a definite and known policy with regard to 
 government deposits is better than the recently developed system of un- 
 certainty and arbitrary action. 
 
 The Movement of Money. The demand for loanable funds 
 varies locally, according to the business conditions that exist in dif- 
 ferent parts of the country. These differences make loans worth 
 more in some localities than in others, and result in some shifting 
 of bank credit. New York banks, for example, sometimes invest 
 in "out of town" commercial paper when this is more profitable 
 than employing their funds at home. More frequently, interior 
 banks place loans in New York, either through their correspondent 
 banks there, or by the purchase of securities from note brokers. 
 
 1 See Finance Report, 1906, p. 41.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 259 
 
 This shifting of credit, however, is unimportant as compared with 
 the movement of money itself. Money is continually flowing from 
 New York to the interior and from the interior to New York, ac- 
 cording as it can be more profitably employed in bank reserves in 
 one place or the other. Similar movements take place between the 
 various cities of the country. This movement, it will be noted, is 
 not one that is apt to disturb financial conditions. On the con- 
 trary, it tends to prevent extreme local fluctuations in money market 
 conditions by leading to the expansion of credit where it is most 
 needed, and similarly, to the contraction of credit where it is least 
 needed. 
 
 There is another kind of money movement, however, which is 
 not so fortunate in its effects upon the money market. The amount 
 of money needed as an actual medium of exchange varies for dif- 
 ferent seasons and for different localities. The demand for money 
 to serve as the basis of credit in bank reserves and the demand for 
 money as an actual medium of exchange are different and compet- 
 ing demands. When more money is needed as a medium of ex- 
 change, reserves have to yield and credit has to be contracted. 
 
 The most important movement of this sort is in response to the 
 annual demand for money to be used in "moving the crops." 
 Harvest expenses are very largely wages, and these have to be paid 
 in cash. Many farmers, moreover, insist on receiving money pay- 
 ments when they sell their crops. The cotton crop of the South 
 and the grain crop of the West necessitate the conversion of bank 
 deposits in those regions into money, and to the negotiation of loans 
 on the security of the crops, the proceeds of which are also taken in 
 cash. The banks in these sections of the country in turn convert 
 their deposits in other banks into money, and in large part this 
 money is obtained, directly and indirectly, from the New York 
 bank reserves. The movement of money from New York to the 
 South and West usually commences in August of each year and 
 continues through November, when the return movement sets in, 
 continuing usually till February. Despite the fact that the New 
 York bankers are forewarned of this movement, it always reduces 
 their surplus reserves and leads to stringent and often precarious 
 Conditions in the New York money market, conditions which are
 
 260 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 frequently reflected in difficulties in the money market throughout 
 the country. 
 
 Elastic Currency. To the arbitrary flow of money to and from 
 the treasury, and to its movement to and from the interior, there 
 must be added the movement of gold between this and other coun- 
 tries. This will be discussed in another place; it is sufficient to 
 note at this point that this external money movement is at the same 
 time a cause and effect of changing money market conditions. 
 
 That these money movements affect the supply of bank credit as 
 they do is partly attributable to the inelastic character of our bond- 
 secured bank currency. Under the provisions of the national bank 
 law that have been described, the variations in the amount of 
 bank notes outstanding bear a close relation to variations in the 
 price of government bonds, and these variations are affected by 
 many other things than money market conditions, and in recent 
 years have been very small. 
 
 As will be seen in Table III, the creation of the two per cent 
 bonds, payable in 1930, stimulated the issue of bank notes, because 
 
 TABLE III 
 
 AMOUNTS OF BANK NOTE CIRCULATION SECURED BY SPECIFIED 
 CLASSES OF BONDS : 1900-1907 l 
 
 SECURITY 
 
 March 13, 
 1900 
 
 Oct. 31, 
 1903 
 
 Oct. 31, 
 1004 
 
 Oct. 31, 
 1005 
 
 Oct. 31, 
 1906 
 
 Oct. 31. 
 1907 
 
 Loan 1908, 3*s . . 
 Loan 1907, 4's . . 
 Loan 1925, 4's . . 
 Loan 1004, 5*5 . . 
 Loan 1891, a's . . 
 Consols 1930, 2's 
 Panama Canal . . 
 
 $56,164,820 
 130,302,250 
 14,697,850 
 21,906,350 
 20,400,150 
 
 $1,797,580 
 2,797,200 
 1,410,100 
 718,650 
 
 $1,922,940 
 5,857,500 
 1,791,600 
 
 $2,215,540 
 4.050-350 
 4,465,000 
 
 $3.73-7oo 
 25,124,650 
 4,602,100 
 
 $6,473.080 
 
 10,732,900 
 
 376,003,300 
 
 416,972,75 
 
 483,181,900 
 
 492,170,650 
 14,482,080 
 
 532,543,550 
 17,245,380 
 
 
 Total 
 
 
 
 
 
 243,651,420 
 
 382,726,830 
 
 426,544,790 
 
 493,912,790 
 
 539,653,180 
 
 566,994,910 
 
 
 From Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, Finance Report, 1907, p. 390. 
 
 the federal tax is only one fourth of one per cent semiannually on 
 bank notes secured by two per cent bonds as against one half of 
 one per cent on notes secured by bonds paying a higher rate of 
 interest. The relative stability of the amount issued in more recent 
 years is noticeable, what increase there was being a natural
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 2 6i 
 
 result of the increasing number and size of banks. Nor does the 
 amount of note issue respond to any marked extent to the regu- 
 lar seasonal demands for money to move the crops or to the less 
 regular operations of the treasury department or of the foreign 
 exchanges. 
 
 Students of banking problems have for many years thought that 
 it would be better to allow the national banks to issue part, if not 
 all, of their notes on the security of their general assets, thus placing 
 them on the same basis as deposits. It is clear that if this were 
 done any sudden increase in the demand for money as a circulat- 
 ing medium might be met by the creation of bank credit in the form 
 of bank notes, or by the shifting of bank credit from the form of 
 deposits to the form of note issues. "Asset banking," as this is 
 called, is used in Canada, and enables the banks there to furnish 
 money for crop moving purposes without endangering their re- 
 serves. Most of the great national banks of continental Europe 
 also issue notes on the security of their general assets. 
 
 To achieve real elasticity it is necessary to provide for the ready 
 contraction of note issues when the special demand for money is 
 over as well as to provide for their ready expansion in time of need. 
 It seems probable that this could best be accomplished under the 
 difficult conditions that prevail in the United States by a system 
 similar in some ways to that governing the Reichsbank of Germany, 
 whereby all note issues above a certain amount are subject to a 
 special tax. This should be coupled, however, with a more ade- 
 quate mechanism for redeeming the notes than the present one, 
 and it would be desirable to graduate the tax according to the 
 amount of the excess note issues outstanding. 
 
 The first tangible result of years of discussion of this subject in Congress 
 and elsewhere was the Aldrich act of 1908. This measure supplements the 
 existing system by permitting banks which have outstanding notes secured 
 by government bonds equal in amount to 40 per cent of their capital to in- 
 crease their circulation in one or both of two ways. First, on the security 
 of approved state, county, or municipal bonds deposited with the treasurer 
 at Washington, such note issues being restricted to 90 per cent of the par 
 value of the bonds. Second, through the voluntary organization of "Na- 
 tional Currency Associations," which are to be composed of not less than 
 ten banks in contiguous territory whose combined capital is not less than
 
 262 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 $5,000,000. Banks in such associations can issue notes to an amount not 
 exceeding 30 per cent of their capital and surplus on the basis of securities 
 deposited with the association, if the securities are approved by the associ- 
 ation and by the comptroller of the currency. Such securities may be (i) 
 bonds of the kind that may be used for the extension of note issue under the 
 alternative plan already mentioned, in which case the issue may be 95 per 
 cent of the par value of the bonds, or (2) two-name commercial paper of 
 not over four months' duration, or the bonds or other securities of corpora- 
 tions, in which case the issue must not exceed 75 per cent of the face value 
 of the securities. The association is responsible for the maintenance of the 
 redemption fund of each of its members. A bank's entire note issue must 
 not exceed its capital and surplus. 
 
 The extra note issues authorized by the Aldrich act must not at any time 
 exceed $500,000,000 in the aggregate, and are taxed at the heavy rate of 5 
 per cent per month for the first month and i per cent for each additional 
 month up to a maximum of 10 per cent. Very little can be expected from 
 the Aldrich act in the way of securing elasticity of the currency. The first 
 of the two alternative methods may possibly be helpful, but the excessive 
 rate of taxation will tend to prevent its extensive use save in extreme emer- 
 gencies. It is difficult to organize national currency associations save in 
 important financial centers, and the provision for the use of corporate securi- 
 ties only projects into the field of note issue what is already an unfortunate 
 tendency of deposit banking in the United States. The Aldrich act may 
 afford some relief in periods of the most extreme stringency in the money 
 market but it does not advance us very far toward the desired goal of a cur- 
 rency that will automatically expand and contract with business needs. 
 Some favor the issue of such a currency by the government instead of the 
 banks, but this would be undesirable. There are no such points of contact 
 between the government treasury and the needs of the business world as 
 exist in the case of the banks. Government paper currency can be controlled 
 in amount only by arbitrary methods. It is by very nature inelastic. 
 
 A Central Bank. The great national banks of European coun- 
 tries, such as the Bank of England, the Bank of France, and the 
 Imperial Bank of Germany, combine the functions of our independ- 
 ent treasury system, the general note issue functions of our national 
 banks, and the function of the New York national banks as cus- 
 todians of the central reserve. That is, they have a practical 
 monopoly of the privilege of issuing notes; 1 they hold the govern- 
 
 1 In England and Germany some other banks than the central banks have a 
 limited right to issue notes, but this is only a survival, a vested right, which in 
 various ways is gradually being extinguished.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 263 
 
 ment funds and act as fiscal agents of the government, and they 
 hold the ultimate banking reserves of their respective countries. 
 
 The United States Bank (1791-1811) and the Second Bank of 
 the United States (1816-1811) were institutions of this kind. In 
 each case Congress refused to recharter the bank at the expiration 
 of its original twenty-year charter. In each case, also, this oc- 
 curred when the country was temporarily under the dominance of 
 a strong democratic sentiment opposed to political or financial cen- 
 tralization in any form. Jealousy on the part of state banks was, 
 however, the immediate cause of the demise of the first United 
 States bank, while the second succumbed to the still more potent 
 hostility of Andrew Jackson. There are many who think that the 
 abandonment of the independent treasury system and the re- 
 establishment of a great central reserve bank would be the best 
 solution of our currency difficulties. Such a bank might very 
 properly be limited to the field of issuing notes, and receiving the 
 deposits of and making loans to the government and other banks. 
 
 The Present Position of State and Private Banks. The figures 
 in Table IV give only a partial idea of the present position of bank- 
 
 TABLE IV 
 
 NUMBER OF BANKS AND AMOUNT OF DEPOSITS IN SPECIFIED KINDS OF 
 
 BANKS: 1907 ' 
 
 
 
 NUMBER or 
 BANKS 
 
 DEPOSITS 
 
 State banks 
 
 0,067 
 
 $3,068,600,000 
 
 Savings banks 
 
 i,4ic 
 
 3 . .10 . .100.000 
 
 Private banks 
 
 1,141 
 
 151,100,000 
 
 Loan and trust companies 
 
 704 
 
 3,061,600,000 
 
 National banks .... 
 
 6,420 
 
 4.722.000.000 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 19,746 
 
 $13,099,600,000 
 
 
 
 
 1 From Report of Comptroller of the Currency, Finance Report, 1007, p. 418. 
 
 ing in the United States, for while they are complete as to national 
 banks, there were, in 1907, over 4000 other banks which failed to 
 make reports to the comptroller of the currency.
 
 264 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 "State banks," in the narrow sense, include only corporations chartered 
 by the individual states to conduct a general commercial banking business. 
 In a broader sense savings banks and trust companies incorporated under 
 state law may be said to be state banks. 
 
 Savings banks do not usually do a commercial banking business ; that is, 
 they are not engaged in the sale of bank credit in a form that can be used in 
 making payments. Their deposit accounts are not usually transferable by 
 means of checks. They receive deposits of small savings and invest them 
 in long time securities, such as real estate mortgages and bonds of various 
 sorts. They perform an important social service by stimulating saving and 
 by increasing the financial power of small investors through concentrating 
 and combining their resources. Savings banks are organized either as cor- 
 porations or as mutual societies managed by a board of trustees acting for 
 the depositors. The latter type is especially common in the eastern states. 
 The advantages of savings banks are less available in the rural districts 
 than in the cities, a fact which is perhaps the strongest argument for the 
 establishment of postal savings banks by the federal government. 
 
 Trust companies were at first organized to take charge of trust funds and 
 to act as executors and administrators of estates. They have, however, 
 developed the functions of both savings banks and commercial banks, and 
 have even entered such specialized banking fields as foreign exchange and 
 the underwriting of corporation securities. They have thus the character 
 of free lances in the banking field. Their banking functions have developed 
 so rapidly that in many states they have been put under no such rigid control 
 as is exercised over state and savings banks. 
 
 Private banks are of two very distinct types. Some are small unincor- 
 porated banks in country towns. Others are great concerns in the financial 
 centers which deal in investment securities, buy and sell foreign exchange, 
 finance great corporate undertakings, and, in some cases, act as brokers in 
 the stock market. 
 
 It is impossible, in fact, to draw a definite line between "banking" and 
 other financial undertakings. Building and loan associations, private money 
 lenders, note brokers, life insurance companies, etc., frequently perform 
 functions which are very much like some kinds of "banking." But banking 
 as the institution which converts personal credit into bank credit in the form 
 of deposit accounts and bank notes is a clearly defined thing, and has a dis- 
 tinct economic significance of its own. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Do you make a loan to the government when you receive greenbacks 
 as money ? 
 
 2. Compare the history of the assignats of the French revolution with 
 the history of the bills of credit issued by the Continental Congress.
 
 CREDIT AND BANKING 
 
 265 
 
 3. Explain the various items in the published "statement" of a national 
 bank. 
 
 4. Because a national bank can buy interest-bearing government bonds 
 and use them as security for its own issues of paper money, advocates of 
 government paper money issues have alleged that it gets "double interest 
 on its money." Is this true? 
 
 5. How should one compare the profitableness of issuing notes with the 
 profitableness of extending deposit credit? 
 
 6. What restrictions does your state impose on state banking corporations ? 
 
 7. Why would wheat not make a satisfactory money commodity? iron? 
 platinum ? diamonds ? 
 
 8. Would it be possible to maintain a seigniorage of 10 per cent on United 
 States gold coinage? 
 
 9. Report on the following questions not answered in this chapter: 
 (i) What is the "limit of tolerance"? (2) On whom does the loss due to 
 the wear of gold coin fall ? (3) To what extent are different kinds of United 
 States money legal tender? 
 
 10. If the United States had adopted the free and unlimited coinage of 
 silver in 1896, how would prices have been affected? 
 
 11. Is the actual standard of value pure gold or gold of standard fineness? 
 
 12. What elements of truth are there in the statement that "coins get 
 their value from the government stamp" ? 
 
 13. Would it be possible to have a standard of value that could not be 
 used as a medium of exchange? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Essays in the Monetary History of the United States. 
 
 CLEVELAND, F. A. Funds and Their Uses. 
 
 Comptroller of the Currency, Annual Report. 
 
 CONANT, C. A. History of Modern Banks of Issue. 
 
 DEWEY, D. R. Financial History of the United States. (See index.) 
 
 Director of the Mint, Annual Report. 
 
 DUNBAR. Chapters on the Theory and History of Banking. 
 
 HEPBURN, A. B. The Contest for Sound Money. 
 
 Indianapolis Monetary Commission, 1898 Report. 
 
 JEVONS, W. S. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. 
 
 JOHNSON, J. F. Money and Currency. 
 
 KIXLEY, DAVID. The Independent Treasury System; also, Money. 
 
 KNOX, J. J. History of Banking in the United States, and United States Notes. 
 
 LAUGHLIN, J. L. History of Bimetallism in the United States, and The 
 
 Principles of Money. 
 MITCHELL, W. C. History of the Greenbacks, and Gold, Prices, and Wages 
 
 under the Greenback Standard. (University of California Publications, 
 
 Economics, Vol. I.)
 
 266 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 No YES, A. D. Thirty Years of Arnerican Finance. 
 
 PRATT, S. S. The Work of Watt Street. 
 
 SCOTT, W. A. Money and Banking. 
 
 SUMNER, W. G. History of Banking in the United States. 
 
 Treasurer of the United States, Annual Report. (This, together with 
 abbreviated forms of the reports of the Director of the Mint and the 
 Comptroller of the Currency, are printed as appendices to the Report 
 of the Secretary of the Treasury in the bound edition of the annual 
 Finance Report.) 
 
 WALKER, F. A. Money, and Money in its Relation to Trade and Industry. 
 
 WATSON, D. K. History of American Coinage. 
 
 WHITE, HORACE. Money and Banking.
 
 CHAPTER XVI 
 OTHER PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 Crises. Crises are frequently recurring phenomena of current 
 economic life. They are of all degrees of severity, but are generally 
 characterized by a scarcity of bank credit, a sudden drop in prices, 
 industrial depression, lack of employment for wage earners, and 
 kindred symptoms. 
 
 Crises are frequently attributed to "over production, " or, when 
 that expression is criticised (because human wants are never fully 
 satisfied) to "under consumption." The two expressions are dif- 
 ferent ways of describing the same thing, and both are misleading 
 because they put the emphasis in the wrong place. Production 
 and consumption have to do with quantities of things and their 
 fitness to satisfy human wants. Crises spring from mishaps in the 
 valuation of things; they relate to what might be called the dollars 
 and cents aspect of economic life. It is difficult, even impossible, 
 for observers to analyze all the factors entering into a particular 
 crisis, and it is even more difficult to formulate a theory of crises 
 that will be of general applicability. There are some important 
 things about crises, however, that are relatively well known, and 
 these will form the basis of our discussion. 
 
 It is a significant fact that crises generally occur only as sharp 
 interruptions of periods of business prosperity, when credit is abun- 
 dant, prices relatively high, and employment plentiful. What- 
 ever may be the cause of a period of exceptional business prosperity, 
 it is apt to contain within itself the seeds of its own destruction. 
 The point will appear clearly if we put together two conclusions 
 that were reached in the preceding chapter: first, that the supply 
 of loanable funds in the form of bank credit is a function of two 
 variables, the supply of personal credit and the supply of money 
 
 267
 
 268 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 available for bank reserves; second, that personal credit is based on 
 the probable amount of future incomes and probable future value 
 of property. 
 
 Suppose, for example, that business conditions are prosperous 
 and promise to continue so, and that there is a plentiful supply of 
 money in the bank reserves. Expected prices and expected profits 
 are large, expected interest payments seem certain. The power to 
 get this future income depends, however, upon the possession of 
 land, capital goods, franchises and other privileges, the estab- 
 lished business relations that give rise to " good-will values," or upon 
 the possession of income-yielding securities, such as mortgages, 
 bonds, stocks, etc. Under such conditions, these things command 
 good prices in the market and may easily be hypothecated, either 
 formally or implicitly, in order to secure purchasing power, 
 bank credit. The bank credit thus created is put into further in- 
 vestments of capital and into the creation of further business 
 opportunities. These things serve in turn, so long as their income- 
 yielding power seems certain, as the basis of further extensions of 
 bank credit, and thus the process of business expansion continues 
 in a cumulative fashion. An extensive period of increasing pros- 
 perity of this kind is, however, scarcely possible unless the supply 
 of money is increasing; for bank reserves as well as the amount of 
 expected personal incomes condition the supply of purchasing 
 power. 
 
 Any one of a number of things may be sufficient to precipitate a 
 panic under such conditions. The whole business structure may 
 fall to pieces through sheer topheaviness. That is, so much pro- 
 duction to-day is indirect, so large a share of productive effort is 
 devoted to forwarding in indirect ways the production of goods that 
 will be ripe for human use only in the comparatively distant future, 
 that the mere operations of supply and demand among business 
 men themselves may maintain prosperous business conditions for 
 some time. But in the long run the maintenance of the values of 
 producers' goods and privileges depends on the demand, and hence 
 on the income, of ultimate consumers. Wages do not usually rise 
 as rapidly as prices in periods of business expansion. This simple 
 fact may in itself keep the average purchasing power of consumers
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 269 
 
 from expanding rapidly enough to furnish a solid support for the 
 growing structure of capital values. 
 
 Crop failures may precipitate a panic by diminishing the pur- 
 chasing power of those engaged in agriculture, and, possibly, by 
 reducing exports and thus necessitating the taking of gold from 
 the bank reserves to ship to Europe in payment for our imports. 
 When the credit situation is at all strained the failure of one im- 
 portant bank may be enough to precipitate a panic. The bank's 
 creditors are prevented from meeting their own obligations; the 
 solvency of others is in turn dependent upon them, and thus losses 
 in expected and often already hypothecated income are transmitted 
 from firm to firm and from industry to industry in a constantly 
 widening circle. 
 
 In fact, whatever may be the immediate cause of a panic, it is 
 bound to grow, in a condition of inflated capital values, with tre- 
 mendous rapidity. The collapse of credit leads to forced sales of 
 property in order that credit obligations may be met. These lower 
 property values, lessen the security on which credit is founded, and 
 render banks less able and less willing to make loans. Moreover, 
 the hoarding of money, which is apt to be a feature of a panic, has 
 a destructive effect on bank reserves. In a serious panic the 
 liquidation of obligations has to work itself out. Then the indus- 
 trial process starts afresh, with lowered values, and with property 
 rights shifted, in some measure, to creditors. 
 
 Crises seem to be unpreventable so long as competition and the 
 credit system dominate in industry. Yet there are some recent 
 developments that may make them less frequent, and possibly less 
 serious. 
 
 The "integration of industry," whereby a whole series of pro- 
 ductive processes, from the production of the raw material to the 
 sale of the finished product, are brought together under one man- 
 agement, decreases the number and complexity of credit relations 
 between producers, and tends to prevent the undue expansion of 
 those parts of the productive process that are farthest removed 
 from the consumer. The strong position of the steel industry in 
 the United States is a case in point. The improvements in the 
 bargaining power of wage earners resulting from their organization
 
 270 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 have enabled them partly to prevent the widening of the gap be- 
 tween wages and prices in prosperous times, as recent American 
 statistics show. On the other hand, crop failures are and always 
 will be a factor of uncertainty. The lack of an elastic currency is 
 also an element of danger, but this can and should be remedied. 
 
 The Economic Effects of Changes in the Value of Money. It 
 has already been suggested that an increase in the amount of 
 money available for bank reserves leads to the expansion of credit, 
 stimulates business, and as a result usually increases prices, 
 temporarily, at least. The same results are achieved, although in 
 not the same way, by a depreciation in the value of money, such as 
 comes from a sudden change in the standard of value, or from the 
 introduction of irredeemable paper money as the medium of ex- 
 cMange. Without understanding the exact process we know that 
 prices are gradually increased under such conditions, there being 
 an unmistakable tendency to adjust them to the change in the 
 "dollar" or other unit of the medium of exchange. 1 The rising 
 prices stimulate business by increasing profits. Profits are in- 
 creased because most of the expenses of production are incurred 
 before the goods are sold, so that the rise in prices increases the 
 margin between prices and the expenses of production, and be- 
 cause, moreover, some of the expenses of production do not usually 
 rise as rapidly as do prices. An expansion of business activity of 
 the kind already described is apt to be the result, and this is not 
 generally soon restrained by insufficient bank reserves, for de- 
 preciated money is usually, though not always, money that is 
 coined or issued in large quantities. 
 
 That periods of prosperity induced in this way are inevitably 
 short-lived and usually end in severe crises does not make them any 
 the less real. Nor should the fact that such artificial conditions 
 of business enterprise are apt to be accompanied by excessive 
 
 1 Possibly the effect upon other prices of the increased prices (measured in 
 the depreciated money) that have to be paid for imported commodities and that 
 are received for exported commodities is the key to this problem, just as it was 
 undoubtedly the chief cause of the rise of prices to fit the bullion value of coins 
 from which seigniorage had been taken. This is the explanation of the rise of 
 prices under the greenbacks suggested by Professor W. C. Mitchell, the historian 
 of that movement.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 271 
 
 speculation and other unhealthy features blind us to the fact that 
 they accomplish some good. The encouragement given to ven- 
 turesome undertakings leads to the trial of new methods of 
 production, to the development of new natural resources, to under- 
 takings of vast proportion, to a general freeing of industrial organi- 
 zation and methods from the restraints of habit and tradition. 
 The foundations of modern large-scale industry in the United 
 States were laid in the period between the Civil War and the panic 
 of 1873. The period of state bank note inflation preceding the 
 panic of 1837 was a period in which the industrial map of the 
 United States was almost wholly changed, and, in the long run, 
 for the better. 
 
 A rapid increase in the supply of standard money may have a 
 similar effect. A tremendous expansion of international trade 
 followed the gold discoveries in California and Australia. In the 
 sixteenth century, increases in the supply of the money metals, 
 economic writers are agreed, hastened the fall of the medizeval 
 economic system. The almost unparalleled development of in- 
 dustry and industrial organization in the United States since 1897, 
 must, with its good features as well as its bad, be attributed in part 
 to the increased supply of gold. 
 
 Business prosperity, however, does not always coincide with the 
 real economic welfare of the masses of the people. If prices are 
 rising faster than money wages, real wages are obviously declining. 
 A period of falling prices is very apt to be a period of increasing 
 well-being for those whose incomes are wages or salaries, although 
 here we have to remember that even if daily or weekly wages do 
 not fall so rapidly as prices, an increase of unemployment may 
 affect total yearly incomes adversely. 
 
 The Standard of Deferred Payments. The relation of changes 
 in the purchasing power of money to long-time debts and credits 
 has been suggested in another connection. If prices increase, the 
 principal of a loan represents less purchasing power at time of re- 
 payment than at the time the loan was made. If prices decrease, 
 the reverse is, of course, true. In periods of cheap money agita- 
 tions the additional burdens imposed upon debtors in a period of 
 decreasing prices are emphasized. An important function of
 
 272 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 money, then, is found in its use as a standard of deferred 
 payments. 1 
 
 As Professor Irving Fisher has shown, there is a partial com- 
 pensation for the injustice worked to debtors or creditors by chang- 
 ing money values in the fact that the interest rate varies inversely 
 with the value of money. If the value of money is increasing and 
 promises to continue to increase, money lenders are forced by com- 
 petition to offset the expected increase in the value of a loan by 
 accepting a lower interest rate. When the value of money is de- 
 creasing, the expected decline in the value of the principal causes a 
 higher rate of interest to be charged. So far then as the increase 
 in the value of the principal is discounted in the interest rate at the 
 time when a loan is made, to that extent is the debtor's claim of in- 
 justice unfounded. The decline in the interest rate as prices de- 
 crease makes it possible, moreover, for debtors to pay off their old 
 obligations with money funds borrowed on more favorable terms. 
 We may expect that less emphasis will be given to the question of 
 the standard of deferred payments in future periods of declining 
 prices, because American farmers are becoming in increasing 
 numbers lenders rather than borrowers of money. Corporation 
 bonds are taking the place of farm mortgages as the most significant 
 form of long-time credit instruments. 
 
 Index Numbers. Changes in the purchasing power of money 
 are indicated statistically by the use of index numbers. 2 The 
 prices of a number of important commodities in some one year, or 
 their average prices for a term of years, are taken as the basis of the 
 computation. The price of each commodity in each year covered 
 
 1 From the analysis in the preceding chapters it should be clear that money 
 serves also as (i) the medium of exchange and measure or denominator of value, 
 (2) the standard of value, (3) the basis of bank credit. The first of these functions 
 is performed by all money; the second function only by standard money and 
 bullion; the third by all money that can be lawfully used in bank reserves. Legal 
 tender money, and, if there are differences in the value of different kinds of money, 
 the cheapest legal tender money, serves as the standard of deferred payments. 
 Before the development of credit facilities one's purchasing power did not depend 
 so much on his property as on his own stock of ready cash. An important early 
 function of money was, accordingly, that of a store or reserve of value or purchasing 
 power. 
 
 * Cf. the table on p. 240.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 2 73 
 
 by the statistics is then stated as a per cent of its price in the basing 
 year or years. The series of per cents thus obtained are called 
 relative prices. These relative prices are then combined into typi- 
 cal prices, or index numbers for each year. Most frequently a 
 simple arithmetic average of the various relative prices for a given 
 year is used as the relative typical relative price. Sometimes a 
 weighted arithmetic average is used. This differs from the simple 
 average in that the relative prices of the more important com- 
 modities are counted more than once in making up the average, 
 the precise amount of weight given to them being fixed according 
 to the importance of the commodities to which they relate. Weight- 
 ing is not of great practical importance unless the list of commodi- 
 ties used is very small, or unless the index number is to be used for 
 some special purpose, such as to show changes in the cost of 
 living, where relative prices are weighted according to the average 
 distribution of the expenditures of families in the wage-earning 
 classes. 
 
 A simple and useful way of obtaining a typical price is to find the 
 median. The median is the relative price which divides all of the 
 relative prices for a given date into halves, one half being lower 
 and one half being higher than the median. Less used are the 
 mode, the relative price that occurs most frequently in a given 
 year, and the geometric average, the wth root of the prod- 
 uct of the relative prices of n commodities. Much has been 
 written about the relative advantages of the different kinds of 
 averages, but the questions involved are highly technical. Whether 
 one kind of average is better than another usually depends upon 
 the character of the data and the use that is to be made of the re- 
 sults. Statisticians now emphasize the importance of knowing 
 the distribution as well as the trend of price changes. That is, in 
 order to know whether the average is really typical of the different 
 relative prices we should know how closely most of them approxi- 
 mate to it. The range of the variation of the different relative 
 prices from the average might, for example, be comparatively 
 small below the average and comparatively large above it. There 
 are various ways of measuring and stating the distribution of 
 prices.
 
 274 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Wage changes as well as price changes can be measured in index 
 numbers. Weighting is of more importance in the case of relative 
 wages than in the case of relative prices, because the number of 
 men represented in the data for single series of relative wages (such 
 as those in a given occupation in a given establishment) is con- 
 stantly changing. 
 
 Index numbers are available for the United States for the period 
 since 1860. For the period 1860-1880 Mitchell's 1 are the best; 
 the period from 1890 to the present is covered by the United States 
 Bureau of Labor, 2 and for the gap from 1880 to 1890 Falkner's are 
 available. 3 Dun's Review and Bradstreei's also publish tables of 
 price changes. 4 
 
 Some writers have suggested the possibility of a tabular standard 
 of value, to be maintained by frequently changing the value of the 
 money unit in accordance with the showings of an officially kept 
 system of index numbers. To do this by periodically altering the 
 amount of bullion in standard money would be impracticable, 
 while to abandon the use of a standard commodity and to attempt 
 to regulate prices by issuing fiat money and controlling the amount 
 in circulation would be, as we have seen, chimerical. A tabular 
 standard of deferred payments might be put in operation by laws 
 providing for the increase or diminution of the principal of debts 
 according to changes in prices. It is probable, however, that this 
 would be satisfactory to neither debtors nor creditors. The really 
 essential thing is to have a commodity standard of value that shall 
 be as stable as possible, and to maintain the convertibility of all 
 other forms of money with it. With gold as the standard of value, 
 and with all other forms of money redeemable in gold, changes in 
 prices are not apt to be rapid enough to work much injustice to 
 either debtor or creditor. The compensating influence of changes 
 in the interest rate must also be taken into account. The question 
 of the grievances of debtors and creditors has been overemphasized 
 
 1 In his Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard. 
 
 3 In various numbers of the Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor. 
 
 "In "Aldrich Report" on Wholesale Prices, Wages, and Transportation, 
 Senate Doc., 32d Cong., ad Session, No. 1394. 
 
 * For an exhaustive account of various index numbers and other price statistics 
 see Laughlin, The Principles of Money, pp. 171-211.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 275 
 
 as compared with the really important economic problems growing 
 out of changes in the value of money. These are, as we have seen, 
 first, the effect on business enterprise, and second, the effect on real 
 incomes as distinguished from money incomes. 
 
 Value of Money. We have not as yet answered one very 
 important question, and that is, "What determines the value of 
 money?" Now by the " value of money" we cannot mean any- 
 thing but the purchasing power of money. There is no such thing 
 in fact as "the general purchasing power of money," although we 
 have found it convenient to use that and similar expressions. 
 Money has, in reality, a large number of different values, measured 
 by the different quantities of different things that it will purchase. 
 If the price of wheat is one dollar per bushel, then one value the 
 wheat value of money is a bushel per dollar. Similarly, the 
 purchasing power of money in sirloin steaks may be four pounds 
 per dollar. But how are we to blend sirloin steaks, wheat, and 
 other things into one concept ? Index numbers do not tell us what 
 the general value of money is; they simply reveal average varia- 
 tions in the different values of money. The concept of the general 
 value of money is simply a useful abstraction, based on a broad 
 view of all its different specific values. 
 
 When we fix our attention upon changes in the various purchas- 
 ing powers of money, however, we are able to make a distinction 
 between changes that are widespread and fairly uniform, and 
 changes that affect only one or two commodities. For example, a 
 new invention may decrease the price of a particular commodity, 
 without affecting the prices of other things except through the 
 shifting of demand from other things to the commodity in question, 
 an effect which would usually be slight so far as the price of any 
 one of these other things is concerned, as the demand would prob- 
 ably be shifted from many different lines of consumption. Or, if 
 the demand for the commodity in question is relatively inelastic, a 
 diminution in its price may increase the demand for other things. 
 But there are, on the other hand, price fluctuations which are wide- 
 spread and fairly uniform, and these we call, with substantial 
 accuracy, changes in the value of money. 
 
 We have already discussed the nature of price fluctuations due
 
 276 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 to the use of a discounted medium of exchange, like the greenbacks, 
 as well as the temporary fluctuations in values, especially capital 
 values, that spring from alternating periods of prosperity and 
 depression in business. But what are the underlying causes of 
 general changes in the value of money ? the kind of changes we 
 referred to when we mentioned the decreasing value of the mone- 
 tary standard itself as a stimulus to business enterprises ? 
 
 Leaving theory aside, we know from experience that, other 
 things being equal, the value of money will decrease when the 
 supply of the standard commodity increases rapidly. 1 We know 
 that the value of money units sometimes increases when the world's 
 supply of the standard metal is being increased only slowly. We 
 then say, and it is only a reasonable inference, that the value of 
 money depends, other things being equal, on the supply and 
 demand of the standard commodity. But this is only an empirical 
 generalization. It leaves us ignorant of the way in which a value 
 equilibrium is really struck between a certain amount of gold and a 
 certain amount of another commodity. 
 
 In analyzing the relation of the supply and demand of other com- 
 modities to their prices, we assumed, for simplicity of the analysis, 
 that the value of gold was not changing. That is, we assumed that 
 the general level of prices was not changing, and so really limited 
 our analysis to the way in which the values of all commodities 
 except gold vary as compared with one another. 
 
 The marginal utility analysis, which formed the basis of our ex- 
 planation of the shifting of demand from one commodity to another, 
 does not help us to explain the demand for gold as money. Mar- 
 ginal utility springs from the capacity of things to satisfy individual 
 wants, and money does not directly satisfy a single human want, 
 except the abnormal wants of the miser. The subjective values we 
 set upon money units are only the reflected values of the things 
 that money will buy for us. 2 
 
 Our standard money commodity is, however, a commodity that 
 
 1 We refer here to a more permanent and thoroughgoing change in the prices 
 than that resulting from the business expansion following an increase in the supply 
 of money available for bank reserves. 
 
 2 When we speak of the utility of money we use the word "utility" in the sense 
 of usefulness, rather than of want-satisfying capacity.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 2 77 
 
 has other than monetary uses. Gold ornaments and other articles 
 made from gold are subject to the law of diminishing utility just as 
 other things are. From the estimates of the director of the mint, 
 it appears that in recent years from one fourth to one third of the 
 world's annual production of gold finds its way into industrial uses. 
 The United States mints and assay offices refine nearly all the crude 
 gold bullion produced in or brought to this country, and allow the 
 depositor to take the proceeds in money or in bars of gold for indus- 
 trial use, as he prefers. There is thus a constant balancing between 
 the industrial and monetary uses of gold. 
 
 In effect the monetary units which can be got by the sale of gold 
 jewelry, etc., for money are balanced against the monetary units 
 which can be got by the simple conversion of bullion into coin. 1 
 Consumers, on the one hand, are balancing the marginal utility of 
 gold jewelry, etc., against the marginal utility of other things that 
 they can buy with the same number of money units. Producers, 
 on the other hand, are balancing the relative profitableness of pro- 
 ducing articles made from gold and articles made from other 
 materials. The valuations placed on gold in its industrial uses, 
 where a direct comparison with the values of other commodities is 
 possible, in this way fix a standard to which the value of gold as 
 money must approximate. 
 
 There is another way in which society makes direct comparisons 
 between the value of gold and the value of other things. Mining, 
 like agriculture, is subject to the law of increasing expenses, and 
 the tendencies of prices to equal marginal expenses is true for both 
 industries. Not only are there marginal mines, mines which it just 
 pays to operate, but in the most productive mines there are mar- 
 gins, certain depths, for example, beyond which the expense of 
 mining more than eats up the value of the product. Through the 
 operators of mines, society is continually comparing the values of 
 the labor and the capital goods used up in the production of gold 
 with the value of the things that can be bought with the produced 
 gold. If the gold produced at the margin will purchase things 
 which consumers value less than they value other things which 
 
 1 The expense of transforming bullion into jewelry, etc., is left out of account, 
 as it does not affect the real point under consideration.
 
 278 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 could have been produced with the use of the same amount of capi- 
 tal and labor, capital and labor will gradually be shifted from its 
 marginal use in gold mining to the production of other things. 
 Here, then, as in the case of the balancing between the monetary 
 and industrial uses of gold, we have a comparative valuation of 
 gold and other things. 
 
 Several years ago the Bureau of the Mint undertook an investi- 
 gation into the relation of the expense of gold mining to the 
 amount of gold produced. Some of the conclusions reached are 
 worth quoting in this connection : 
 
 In every mining district there are mines producing at good profits, mines 
 producing at small profits, mines barely paying expenses, and mines 
 operated at a loss, but with the hope that they will do better. Every increase 
 in costs would submerge the latter more deeply, add to the list of the un- 
 profitable, and probably close some of them. ... A higher scale of working 
 costs will bring losing experiments to an earlier conclusion, reduce profits, 
 and make mining ventures generally less attractive, and thus diminish the 
 output. 1 
 
 To summarize our conclusions: The law of marginal utility ap- 
 plies in the industrial uses of gold. The particular form of the law 
 of normal value that is operative in agriculture also holds true in 
 gold mining (although it has to be stated in a somewhat different 
 way.) An increase in the supply of gold diminishes its marginal 
 utility in industrial uses, that is, diminishes the valuation put on 
 gold as compared with other commodities. This is bound to affect 
 the value of gold as money, on account of the ease with which the 
 supply of gold can be shifted to one use or the other. The resulting 
 increase in prices may be slow and irregular, but it is none the less 
 certain. The rise of prices, however, cannot continue indefinitely. 
 The increase of prices and wages brings increasing expenses in 
 gold mining. The marginal part of the supply of gold will nor- 
 mally be cut off, a process which will continue until a rise in the 
 value of gold diminishes the expense of producing it. 
 
 These suggestions are not put forward as an exhaustive state- 
 ment of all the relations between the supply of gold and its value, 
 although they are possibly the most important ones. Increases in 
 
 1 Report on the Production of the Precious Metals,* 1904, p. 41.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 279 
 
 the quantity of other kinds of money and improvements in the 
 mechanism of credit, for example, probably have an effect on prices 
 similar to that of an increase in the quantity of gold, in that they 
 economize the use of that metal. Silver and paper money do not 
 
 TABLE I 
 PRODUCTION OF GOLD IN THE WORLD SINCE 1841 
 
 (From 1841 to 1885 the estimate is from a table of averages for certain periods, compiled 
 by Dr. Adolph Soetbeer; for the years 1886 to 1006 the production is the annual estimate of 
 the Bureau of the Mint.) 
 
 PERIOD 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE FOR PERIOD 
 
 FINE OUNCES 
 
 VALUE 
 
 1841-1850 
 
 1,760,502 
 
 $3 6 >393> 000 
 
 1851-1855 
 
 6,410,324 
 
 132,513,000 
 
 1856-1860 
 
 6,486,262 
 
 134,083,000 
 
 1861-1865 
 
 5.949.582 
 
 122,989,000 
 
 1866-1870 
 
 6,270,086 
 
 129,614,000 
 
 1871-1875 
 
 5,591,014 
 
 115,577,000 
 
 1876-1880 
 
 5.543." 
 
 114,586,000 
 
 1881-1885 
 
 4,794,755 
 
 99,116,000 
 
 1886-1890 
 
 5,461,282 
 
 112,895,000 
 
 1891-1895 
 
 7,882,565 
 
 162,947,000 
 
 1896-1900 
 
 12,446,939 
 
 257,301,100 
 
 1901 
 
 12,625,527 
 
 260,992,900 
 
 1902 
 
 i4,354,68o 
 
 296,737,600 
 
 1903 
 
 15,852,620 
 
 327,702,700 
 
 1904 
 
 16,804,372 
 
 347,377,200 
 
 I90S 
 
 18,268,696 
 
 377,647, 7 
 
 1906 
 
 i9,3 66 .55 
 
 400,342,100 
 
 take the place of an equivalent amount of gold, however, because 
 some gold has to be held in reserve to maintain their convertibility. 
 
 The so-called "quantity theory" of the value of gold money has been 
 much discussed in recent years. This is the doctrine that, other things being 
 equal, prices vary inversely as the amount of money in circulation. In 
 reality many different theories of the value of money have been put forward 
 under the name of the quantity theory. The theory just outlined, for 
 example, may be called a conservative form of the quantity theory. Some 
 statements of the theory are open to objection because they (i) place too
 
 280 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 much stress on the very doubtful problem of the exact mathematical ratio 
 between variations in the quantity of money and variations in prices, or 
 (2) confuse the "measure" or "denominator" of value with the standard of 
 value, or (3) fail to recognize the necessity of a commodity standard of value, 
 and consequently attach no significance to the influence of the industrial 
 use of the standard commodity on its value. The most extreme form of 
 the quantity theory is that which forms the foundation of the argument 
 for the possibility of fiat money. 
 
 The Increase in the Production of Gold. Although probably 
 more gold was produced between 1850 and 1875 than from 1492 to 
 1850, yet, as Table I shows, the production of gold in any three 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 RECENT PRODUCTION OF GOLD IN DIFFERENT COUNTRIES l 
 (In thousands of kilograms) 
 
 COUNTRY 
 
 1897 
 
 IQOO 
 
 1904 
 
 Africa 
 
 88 
 
 I 7. 
 
 1 20 
 
 Australia 
 
 07 
 
 Ill 
 
 132 
 
 United States and Alaska 
 
 86 
 
 no 
 
 121 
 
 Russia 
 
 3=; 
 
 7T 
 
 77 
 
 Canada 
 
 
 42 
 
 2C 
 
 British India 
 
 12 
 
 
 18 
 
 Mexico 
 
 II 
 
 17 
 
 10 
 
 China 
 
 
 8 
 
 7 
 
 All others 
 
 26 
 
 7.C 
 
 7C 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total . . 
 
 2CC 
 
 ^s? 
 
 Ml 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 From Journal of Political Economy, Vol. X, p. 580, and Finance Report, 1007, p. 363. 
 
 years since 1896 or in any two years since 1902 was as great as the 
 total production in the period first mentioned. Most of this great 
 output of gold, as Table II indicates, comes from relatively few 
 countries. At present the British empire supplies over one half 
 and the United States (including Alaska) nearly one fourth of the 
 total product. The causes of this enormous increase were, in part, 
 the opening up of new gold fields in South Africa, Canada, Alaska, 
 and Colorado, and in part the improvements in methods of extract- 
 ing gold from low grade and refractory ores, in which connection
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 28l 
 
 
 M tt M 00 
 VO (N t^ 00 M 
 f*5 O M O N 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 CO 
 
 NO Q *^ 
 
 M O NO 
 
 o o NO 
 
 "5 
 
 CO 
 
 -0 
 
 
 
 o< 
 
 CO 
 
 10 
 
 J 
 
 i 
 
 oo co oo o <* 
 00 9 *O v V) 
 
 M *O t^ N tj- 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 fo 
 
 HI CO 1^ 
 
 00 CO 00 
 ON T 
 
 vC 
 
 I/-, 
 
 
 
 <*5 
 
 Tf 
 U1 
 
 H 
 
 !>. O CO CO O 
 ro W \O ro 
 M CO 10 H 
 W M" 
 
 M 
 
 t^ 
 
 M 
 
 oT 
 
 >O IO w 
 
 * Q 
 
 fO O 
 
 -t 
 10 
 
 o* 
 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 M 
 
 PO 
 
 x 
 z z 
 
 < 
 
 Tt t^ P 
 
 t-~ M \O 
 
 . \o f5 r<0 
 
 fp 
 
 O 
 
 rr> 
 
 NO to OO 
 
 HI tr> -t- 
 
 CO to M 
 
 o 
 o> 
 
 -r 
 
 Ch 
 t^. CO 
 
 oo in 
 
 ^ 
 
 ^0 
 -r 
 
 s, 
 
 WJ 
 
 g P 
 
 S e 1 
 
 to M O 
 
 : o\ w co 
 
 . O -t O 
 
 1 
 
 w to NO 
 ON f Cl 
 
 ro O NO 
 
 ON 
 
 
 
 t~* OO 
 
 f-J N 
 
 CO CO 
 
 >0 
 
 S 
 
 
 * 
 t^ 
 
 < s 
 
 ! a 
 
 iC^ 
 
 ro w 
 ^ 
 
 t- 
 IO 
 
 to 
 
 >O *5 
 CO IO 
 
 IH \O 
 
 O 
 
 -T 
 t^. 
 
 N t^ 
 
 vO 00 
 ro f*5 
 
 
 <r, 
 t^ 
 
 to 
 
 5 
 
 cT 
 
 (n 
 
 H 
 
 Z t~ 
 < 
 
 W Ch 
 
 . r^ t^ O 
 
 . O\ w <~O 
 4 ^ M - . 
 
 <o 
 
 'O 
 
 . 
 
 o\ . * 
 
 <T> xr> 
 cs O\ 
 
 (*J 
 
 O 
 
 vO 
 
 N ro 
 t "?. 
 
 -0 
 i/-. 
 
 
 M 
 O 
 
 z 8 
 
 6 
 
 II 
 
 z 
 
 hH 
 
 8Ch ON 
 CS t~ 
 
 . VO~ fT N" 
 
 CO IH H 
 . . M 
 <& 
 
 o 
 
 M 
 CN1 
 
 r^ M 
 
 00^ c^ 
 
 o" ^> 
 >O ro 
 
 M . 
 
 
 
 T? 
 
 o> 
 
 M 
 
 ^ OO 
 M ro 
 
 iC N" 
 
 *) CO 
 
 w 
 
 M 
 
 <e 
 
 <> 
 
 M 
 
 r--. 
 
 o 
 
 q\ 
 <* 
 
 N 
 
 t>. 
 
 >l 
 
 D 
 
 w * O 00 ~- 
 \O w O ^ M 
 rO O ON tO CO 
 
 O 
 
 v? 
 
 H IT) IT) 
 
 \o o *o 
 
 O\ * <0 
 
 M 
 O 
 
 q; 
 
 O to 
 t--. l~- 
 in f 
 
 m 
 
 -t 
 r^ 
 
 
 S 
 
 M 
 1 
 
 OO CO O ON * 
 CO M t~, ro t^- 
 O vO O to NO 
 
 8 
 
 O~ N O 
 M M Tj- 
 Tj- O 
 
 | 
 
 CN 
 
 N tri 
 IT) \O 
 ro ir> 
 
 00 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 H 
 ?; 
 
 t^ \O t^ NO CO 
 
 ro NO CO 
 
 A ^ * 
 
 NO 
 O 
 
 * 
 
 H 
 
 <t * 
 M 
 
 00 
 
 H 
 
 OO 1C 
 t^. 
 
 ( 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 n 
 
 
 
 
 
 te 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 M y ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 j| 
 
 "3 
 o : ; 
 
 
 S. ^ : 
 
 rt C 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 Gold bullion 
 Silver bullion 
 Gold coin 
 Silver dollars 
 Subsidiary silver coin. . 
 
 Total metallic .... 
 
 P 
 
 Legal tender notes (gree 
 Legal tender notes (of i 
 National bank notes. . . 
 
 to 
 
 -i 
 
 
 
 ~2 
 "c 
 H 
 
 Gold certificates 
 Silver certificates 
 
 Total certificates. . 
 
 1 
 
 T) 
 fi 
 
 O
 
 282 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the development of the "cyanide process" has been of special im- 
 portance. 1 Dredging for gold in the beds of rivers which drain 
 gold-yielding lands, is a very recent development that promises to 
 be of considerable importance. Notwithstanding the decrease in 
 the value of gold, the bulk of the gold produced in California to-day 
 is from ore bodies that twenty- five or thirty years ago were generally 
 considered worthless. 
 
 The effects of this enormous output have been felt in both Europe 
 and America in a general increase of both prices and wages. There 
 are some who expect that the value of gold will continue to depreci- 
 ate for a long time in the future. Account must be taken, however, 
 of the automatic check which the increase in wages and prices is 
 bound to put on the production of gold by increasing mining ex- 
 penses. On the other hand, still further economies in productive 
 methods are possible. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Report on the Note Issue systems of Canadian banks, the Bank 
 of England, the Bank of France, and the Imperial Bank of Germany. 
 
 2. Make a diagram showing the weekly changes in the total reserves 
 and the surplus reserves of New York clearing house banks for any recent 
 year. (Statistics may be obtained from the annual Financial Review, the 
 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, the Banker's Magazine, or other finan- 
 cial journal.) 
 
 3. Construct a simple index number for wholesale prices, in one city, 
 covering the period of a few weeks. (Use the market quotations of a daily 
 paper as data.) 
 
 4. If half the gold in the world were destroyed, would prices be doubled ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 (See also references for Chap. XV.) 
 
 ADAMS, T. S. "Index Numbers and the Standard of Value," Journal of 
 Political Economy, December, 1901, March, 1902. 
 
 1 "There are many mines in operation now at a profit which could not have been 
 worked at a profit ten years ago. There has been an important addition to the 
 gold and silver product by the recovery of these metals from lead and copper ores 
 by modern processes. The most important gains seem to have come, however, 
 through economies in management, particularly by enlarging the scale of opera- 
 tions and by more complete extraction of the values from the ores treated." 
 Report on the Production of the Precious Metals, 1904, p. 41.
 
 PROBLEMS IN MONEY AND BANKING 283 
 
 BURTON, T. E. Crises and Depressions. 
 
 BOWLEY, A. L. Statistics, Chap. VII. 
 
 Director of the Mint. Annual Report on the Production of the Precious 
 
 Metals. 
 
 JONES, E. D. Economic Crises. 
 MAYO-SMITH, Statistics and Economics. 
 United States Geological Survey, annual volume on the Mineral Industry.
 
 CHAPTER XVII 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 THE subject of international trade brings us to an examination 
 of exchange from a new viewpoint. In principle, international 
 trade does not differ essentially from other kinds of trade. In the 
 last analysis it amounts to an aggregate of exchanges between pairs 
 of traders. But in discussing international trade we lay the em- 
 phasis upon the aggregate rather than the specific exchange, take 
 a larger view of commercial relations, try to determine how great 
 districts of the world combine to supply one another's wants, and 
 analyze the machinery by which commerce overcomes the obsta- 
 cles of trade restrictions and the difficulties growing out of the use 
 of different monetary units in different parts of the world. Much 
 of the confusion met with in this branch of economic thought is 
 due to mere forgetfulness of the elementary axioms of exchange, 
 and for this reason it is desirable, even at the cost of some repe- 
 tition, to reexamine briefly the nature and function of trade. 
 
 Nature and Advantage of International Trade. The function 
 of trade is to create the utilities of time and place. Industry 
 itself, " production " in the narrow sense of the word, is like- 
 wise confined to the creation of utilities form utilities, prin- 
 cipally. Trade, therefore, is as beneficial, as truly productive, as 
 agriculture or manufactures. The American people are just as 
 truly engaged in production when they buy books from Germany 
 as when they cut down their own spruce trees and manufacture 
 them into paper for the "yellow journals." 
 
 Trade is not only productive in the sense that it creates utilities, 
 but it is also an indispensable part or process of the division of 
 labor. Upon this self-evident fact it is unnecessary to dwell. It 
 is, however, desirable to recall the fact that specialization of func- 
 
 284
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 285 
 
 tion is profitable even to those individuals or classes which are 
 plainly superior in general productive efficiency. A successful 
 lawyer does not write his own letters, even though he is an expert 
 operator on the typewriter. He specializes in that occupation in 
 which he has the greatest advantage, and hires some one to 
 write his letters for him. 
 
 This rule frequently referred to as the law of comparative costs 
 - holds for communities and nations, as well as for individuals. 
 If, in Holland, it costs ten times as much to produce a barrel of 
 flour as a yard of cloth, while in America it costs only six times as 
 much, it will be profitable for the Dutch to confine themselves to 
 the production of cloth, and for the Americans to confine themselves 
 to the production of flour; even though both flour and cloth could 
 be produced more cheaply in America than in Holland. * 
 
 If this conclusion is true, it follows that so long as the compara- 
 tive costs of producing goods vary among the different nations of 
 the world, so long there will be some international trade. And, 
 furthermore, since it is impossible to conceive that the costs of 
 producing all kinds of transportable goods will ever be exactly 
 proportional in the several countries of the world, it is evident that 
 international trading is bound to continue. It can be permanently 
 suppressed only by raising freight charges to a prohibitive level, 
 or by deliberately manipulating customs tariffs so as to suppress 
 every new international trade connection as soon as it springs up, 
 or by the complete destruction of industry in other parts of the 
 world; and none of these possibilities is ever likely to be realized. 
 The ideal of an exclusive home market is a delusion. The last 
 thirty years have witnessed a remarkable increase of protection 
 throughout the civilized world, but international trade has in- 
 creased by leaps and bounds. 
 
 International trade, then, is productive, profitable, and for prac- 
 tical purposes irrepressible. The tariff controversy can never be 
 settled until these elementary truths are thoroughly appreciated. 
 On the other hand, it is equally plain that these facts do not settle 
 the tariff controversy. Ordinarily, trade is mutually advantageous 
 
 1 Assuming, as Mill points out, that capital and labor will not emigrate 
 tn masse from Holland to America, and that freight charges are small.
 
 286 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 to both parties; and in one sense it is always so. If Smith trades 
 x to Jones for y, Smith must have wanted y more than x, and 
 Jones must have wanted x more than y, so that the temporary 
 happiness of both is increased by the transaction. But this is not, 
 as has sometimes been intimated, sufficient reason for permitting 
 all kinds of trade and condemning all kinds of trade restrictions. 
 If Smith is an ignorant Indian, x a blue fox pelt, Jones an un- 
 scrupulous trader, and y a pint bottle of adulterated whisky, the 
 " sense " in which this trade is adjudged " mutually profitable " 
 is scarcely distinguishable from nonsense. The logic which ap- 
 proves unrestricted trading of this sort would also sanction unre- 
 stricted child labor and the contemptible extortion of the " loan 
 shark " who charges a desperate widow 200 per cent a year on a 
 small loan which the woman in her ignorance and necessity 
 must secure. Trade restrictions have existed as long as 
 international trade itself, and the real problem is not whether 
 there should be any restriction, but when and where particular 
 varieties of restraint are justifiable. 
 
 Restriction of International Trade. In ancient times among 
 many nations, such as the Hebrews and Chinese, contact with other 
 peoples was feared and foreign trade was practically prohibited. 
 In Greece and Rome the greatest thinkers entertained a profound 
 contempt for trade, based in part upon the belief that in exchange 
 one party is usually cheated; and this prejudice was partially 
 justified by the character of the primitive trader who was part 
 sailor, part pirate, part merchant, and took all the profit he could 
 possibly extort in every transaction as insurance against the great 
 risks of his calling. 
 
 At a later date, in the middle ages, when commerce between 
 the semi-L dependent cities of western Europe increased, trade 
 came to be highly prized by the average citizen, although it was 
 still condemned by the philosophic schoolmen; and it was regu- 
 lated in the most exclusive spirit. 
 
 " Every effort was made to keep trade as much as possible in the hands 
 of native citizens. For example, the Venetians forbade the Germans from en- 
 gaging in trade with the East by way of Venice, and the citizens of Lubeck strove 
 to keep the Baltic trade from the Dutch. . . . Foreigners were mistrusted
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 287 
 
 and partnerships with them were forbidden. Foreign visitors were restricted 
 in many ways in their commercial dealings with native citizens. Many 
 occupations were closed to them ; the length of their sojourn and the number 
 of their visits were limited; they could not pass a town without exposing their 
 wares for sale and paying the required market dues. The wants of the con- 
 sumer took precedence over those of the producer or merchant. At the 
 weekly markets consumers could supply their needs before the baker or mer- 
 chant was allowed to make purchases. There was a community interest 
 in the supplies of necessities, and often their exportation was prohibited. The 
 trade of neighboring peasants was restricted to the home city, and laws 
 regulating price, weight, measure, and quality were common. This restrict- 
 ive municipal policy was very much relaxed at the great fairs which were 
 held periodically in various parts of Europe." l 
 
 In the early modern period mercantilism became dominant. 
 Commercial policies were controlled by the desire to get and keep 
 the precious metals. At first the exportation of specie was pro- 
 hibited; merchants trading abroad were compelled to bring home 
 cash for the goods they had taken out with them; foreign mer- 
 chants trading within the home country were compelled to 
 exchange their cash for domestic goods before they departed; 
 exportation except the exportation of raw materials needed 
 in the manufacturing industries was encouraged; and impor- 
 tation except in the case of the precious metals and skilled 
 artizans who were encouraged to immigrate was discouraged 
 or prohibited. When it became apparent that the supply of 
 money had to be secured through international trading, the 
 greatest emphasis came to be laid upon the " favorable balance 
 of trade "; and means, ranging all the way from bounties to 
 war, were vigorously employed to secure the carrying trade for 
 native ships. In a large historical sense mercantilism was merely 
 a cry elicited by one of the sharpest of the world's great growing 
 pains. It was a symptom more than a cause or an explanation. 
 It marked the establishment of the division of labor on a territorial 
 basis, and recorded the replacement of the independent economy 
 of the middle ages by the modern economy of exchange. For 
 the latter, money was indispensable, and had to be secured at any 
 cost. 
 
 1 Professor G. M. Fisk, International Commercial Policies, pp. 15-16. 

 
 288 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The mercantilist period has been followed after a brief 
 laissez-faire reaction in some countries by the period of protec- 
 tion in which we still linger. The extensive taxation of imports 
 still continues; but trade prohibitions, export and transit duties, 
 have been largely abandoned in the more advanced countries. In 
 the United States export duties are prohibited by constitutional 
 law. But few nations have wholly risen above mercantilist prac- 
 tices. Canada prohibits the importation of oleomargarine and 
 similar substitutes for butter ; Great Britain prohibits the impor- 
 tation of sugar from countries paying bounties on its production; 
 Switzerland levies an export tax on cattle, hides, and skins shipped 
 from the country, while Norway and Sweden tax the exportation 
 of timber ; and Russia still attempts to control the Persian trade 
 by levying transit duties upon goods passing through her terri- 
 tories destined for Persia. But export and transit duties in their 
 old mercantilist uses have nearly disappeared. 
 
 Extensive use is still made of export taxes for revenue purposes in South 
 America and the Orient; and trade prohibitions based upon grounds of 
 sanitation, morals, and what Americans call the "police powers," are in- 
 creasing rather than decreasing. Turkey, for instance, levies an ad valorem 
 tax of i per cent upon all exports; and in general the most important 
 tropical products are still subject to export taxes. As for trade prohibitions 
 the continued necessity for their occasional employment is illustrated by our 
 federal law authorizing the President to suspend the importation of any 
 article which he regards as " dangerous to the health or welfare of the people 
 of the United States." For a more complete enumeration of modern export 
 duties and trade prohibitions, see Fisk's International Commercial Policies,, 
 Chap. VI. 
 
 Mercantilist ideas die hard, and current discussion of inter- 
 national trade by reputable legislators and intelligent journalists 
 is still permeated with fallacious notions which had their origin in 
 the conditions and economic philosophy of the seventeenth century. 
 One of these notions, the idea that there is something essentially 
 favorable in an excess of exports, and something essentially un- 
 favorable in an excess of imports, demands careful consideration. 
 
 Balance of Trade. Suppose, for purposes of discussion, that 
 the United States succeeded in prohibiting imports for a long 
 period, while at the same time it succeeded in selling a large
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 289 
 
 amount of merchandise to foreign purchasers. What would 
 happen? Evidently a large portion of the money of the world 
 would accumulate in the vaults of American bankers, interest 
 rates would fall, possibly to rise again later, and eventually, 
 if the process continued long enough, the prices of American com- 
 modities would ascend to such a level that foreign nations would 
 be unable to continue buying in this country. At this point, 
 evidently, our hypothesis breaks down, and we are forced to con- 
 clude that the original supposition was an impossible one. 
 
 This hypothetical case and its reductio ad absurdum are sufficient 
 to establish certain important practical conclusions. The first is 
 that a country cannot permanently sell goods for money alone. 
 If it produces large quantities of the money metals, it will regu- 
 larly sell those metals for the goods and services of other nations. 
 If it produces no gold or silver itself, it will secure them through 
 exchange; although, even in this case, gold and silver are likely to 
 constitute only a minor part of its imports. Perhaps the gravest 
 error one can commit in studying an international trafle balance 
 is to treat it as an exchange of goods for money. It is not even an 
 exchange of goods for goods. The true international balance is 
 one of claims against obligations, of credits against debits. The 
 complete statement is that the goods, moneys, and services ren- 
 dered by one country to other countries, plus its claims and credits 
 of all kinds, will be balanced by the goods, moneys, and services 
 received by the same country plus its debts and obligations of all 
 kinds. Or, to put the matter concretely, we must include, along with 
 the exports and imports of merchandise and bullion, loans which 
 the country makes or receives, annual interest payments on loans 
 and capital invested abroad, repayment of loans or the purchase 
 of securities, earnings of ships, insurance premiums, and commis- 
 sions of all kinds for international services, governmental ex- 
 penditures in foreign countries for diplomatic service, payment 
 of subsidies and war indemnities, remittances of immigrants, 
 expenditures of travelers, and a thousand and one other items, 
 all tending, according as they depress or raise the price of foreign 
 exchange, to bring about the importation or exportation of gold 
 for the occasional balancing of the account.
 
 290 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 A mere glance at this list of items entering into foreign trade is 
 sufficient to puncture the old mercantilist idea that a "favorable 
 balance of trade " or an excess of merchandise exports brings about 
 an increase of the money supply. This idea is as fully refuted by 
 commercial statistics as by economic analysis. In the thirty-three 
 years, 1874-1906, for instance, we had a large excess of merchan- 
 dise exports in all except four years, but there was an excess of 
 gold imports in only sixteen years. So, similarly, there is no neces- 
 sary truth in the statement which we hear so often, that our present 
 "favorable balance" indicates that the United States is settling its 
 indebtedness to foreign capitalists, repurchasing American securi- 
 ties owned abroad, and thus bringing the control of American 
 enterprises more completely into the hands of Americans. It may 
 mean this, to be sure, but it may also merely mean that we are 
 paying England in goods for carrying and insuring our exports, 
 or that foreign owners of American securities are taking in this 
 form the annual interest or profits due to them. The recent excess 
 of export* may thus represent the continuance of indebtedness 
 rather than its liquidation. For the same reasons an "unfavor- 
 able balance of trade " or an excess of merchandise imports is open 
 to a variety of different interpretations. It may mean that foreign 
 capital is investing more heavily in the country under discussion, 
 or that this country is taking, in the form of consumable commodi- 
 ties, interest and profits on investments which it has previously 
 made abroad, or that it is selling its holdings in foreign enterprises 
 and taking the proceeds in the form of consumable goods. An 
 "unfavorable balance" of trade may thus be, in reality, highly 
 encouraging; and a "favorable balance" indicative of national 
 waste and extravagance. The precise meaning of any particular 
 balance can only be determined after the most careful study, and 
 no dependence should be placed upon the offhand interpretations 
 of casual investigators. The great truth is that there must be 
 some sort of balance between the credits and liabilities of any 
 country, and that in practice a nation must be willing to buy if it 
 is anxious to sell. 
 
 A scholarly analysis of the foreign trade of the United States, with a careful 
 interpretation of the meaning of the trade balance at various periods, may
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 291 
 
 be found in the North American Review for July, 1901, from the pen of 
 Professor C. J. Bullock. Professor Bullock's explanation of the balance in 
 two or three periods may be given, in order to illustrate the variety of factors 
 which must be taken into account when dealing with this subject. In the 
 period 1789-1820 the imports of merchandise and specie exceeded the cor- 
 responding exports by $511,000,000, and our obligations were further in- 
 creased by interest on foreign capital invested in the United States to the 
 amount of $200,000,000 approximately. This total indebtedness of some- 
 thing over $700,000,000 was offset by the earnings of the American mer- 
 chant marine, estimated at about $800,000,000 for the period in question. 
 " So far, then, from the country being drained of its money in payment for 
 the balance of imported merchandise, the banks held not less than $20,000,- 
 ooo of specie in the year 1820; while Gallatin and Crawford estimated that 
 there had never been more hard cash in circulation." 
 
 In the decade 1831-1840, owing to the high prices current in this country, 
 imports exceeded exports by $159,700,000; the imports of specie also ex- 
 ceeded the exports by $50,650,000 ; and the earnings of our merchant marine, 
 $90,000,000, sufficed only to reduce this "unfavorable balance" to about 
 $120,000,000. This remaining balance is accounted for by new foreign 
 investments in the United States, in particular by foreign purchases of state 
 bonds. "Our large imports of merchandise and specie had been made 
 necessary by the movement of foreign capital toward the United States." 
 
 In the decade 1851-1860 the merchandise imports again exceeded the ex- 
 ports by $355,800,000; the net amount due to foreign creditors was some- 
 where between $100,000,000 and $130,000,000; and to offset these adverse 
 balances our merchant marine earned in this period only $158,000,000. The 
 remaining balance in this case was covered by our large excess of specie 
 exports, which amounted to $417,608,000, and was due to the discovery of 
 gold in California. " The United States had become one of the leading gold- 
 producing regions, and the course of the exchanges was inevitably altered." 
 
 In the periods briefly described above, the striking factors in our inter- 
 national trade were, respectively, the earnings of our merchant marine, new 
 investments of foreign capital in the United States, and large specie exports 
 following the discovery of gold in California. In the last period, from 1874 
 to 1896, our exports both of merchandise and specie greatly exceeded our 
 imports. "This meant simply," concludes Professor Bullock, "that the 
 country had assumed its normal position as a debtor nation on the various 
 items of invisible exchanges, and was paying annually something like 
 $122,500,000 on such accounts." 
 
 In concluding this aspect of the subject the student should be warned that 
 trade statistics are full of pitfalls for the unwary and can safely be handled 
 only by experts. Exports are sometimes overvalued, imports are generally 
 undervalued; some countries state values at the point of departure (thus 
 excluding cost of carriage) ; other countries state values at the point of entry
 
 292 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 (thus including cost of carriage) ; some countries make special efforts to ex- 
 clude values of re exported goods from their statistics; others make little 
 or no effort to eliminate such nominal items ; while the complete prevention 
 of such reduplication is probably impossible. Eminent statisticians are now 
 making earnest effort to harmonize the trade statistics of the various countries 
 of the world, but it will be a long time before trustworthy conclusions con- 
 cerning the real significance of the so-called balance of trade can be drawn 
 by the average student. 
 
 Foreign Exchange. The preceding discussion makes it clear 
 that, compared to the enormous values of the goods exchanged in 
 international trade, only a small amount of money is used. As 
 in domestic trade, purchase is set against sale, debt canceled by 
 credit, and money employed only for the occasional settlement of 
 balances. This cancellation of offsetting claims is effected by the 
 banks and brokers who engage in foreign exchange; and a brief 
 description of their economic function becomes necessary at this 
 point. For it should never be forgotten that the international 
 banker has been in the past and will be in the future an indis- 
 pensable factor in the development of foreign trade. Without 
 his good offices the vast international traffic of the world would be 
 but a shadow of what it now is. It need hardly be said, more- 
 over, that in its detailed operation the work of foreign exchange 
 is exceedingly complex, and that only a sketch of the essentials of 
 the process can be given here. 
 
 As illustrative of the process, let us take the important case of 
 our trade with England. Ordinarily, an American exporter who 
 has sold goods to England draws an order a bill of exchange 
 on the English debtor, directing him to pay the claim at some 
 specified time and place in London. American importers, on the 
 other hand, commonly pay their foreign balances by buying bills 
 of exchange, or drafts on London, and sending them to their Eng- 
 lish creditors. In this way American debts and credits are bal- 
 anced in London without transferring any money at all, except 
 occasionally to settle the balance of indebtedness. 
 
 Bills of exchange differ from ordinary drafts in that the latter 
 are usually drawn on a bank, while the bill is drawn on a com- 
 mercial creditor. They are usually accompanied by bills of 
 lading, insurance receipts, certificates of weight and origin, and
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 293 
 
 all the documents necessary to give the purchaser of the bill full 
 title to the goods until the bill is accepted or paid. They are 
 accordingly referred to as "documentary bills" or "commercial 
 bills," to -distinguish them from "bankers' bills" and other instru- 
 ments of international credit described hereafter. Documentary 
 bills are freely negotiable, passing from hand to hand by indorse- 
 ment, and gathering strength with each new indorsement. It is 
 important, also, to note the difference between "sight bills" and 
 "long bills," the former calling for payment upon presentation, 
 the latter for immediate "acceptance" by the drawee and payment 
 after thirty, sixty, or ninety days. The price of ninety-day bills, 
 for instance, is fixed by the price of sight bills and the discount 
 rate in London. 
 
 \Ve may now enlarge our simplified illustration to something 
 like life-size. Documentary bills drawn by exporters or creditors 
 all over the country are sold by the drawers to bankers, usually 
 New York bankers, who may be called the "wholesalers of ex- 
 change." The sale may be either direct or through exchange 
 brokers, "the jobbers of exchange." These documentary bills 
 are sent by the New York banks to their foreign correspondents for 
 collection (in the case of sight bills) or acceptance (in the case 
 of long bills). The balances thus built up abroad by the New 
 York banks constitute the fund against which they draw their 
 own bills. These are sold directly or through smaller banks 
 the "retailers of exchange" located in all parts of the 
 country. Foreign exchange is sold ii\ a great variety of forms 
 bankers' drafts, travelers' checks, travelers' letters of credit, 
 commercial letters of credit, cable transfers, and the like 
 descriptions of which may be found in the references cited at the 
 end of the chapter. 
 
 The illustrations used above, while typical of a large part of the 
 foreign exchange of this country, fail to represent adequately the 
 complexity which marks some of the interactions of international 
 credit. An illustration of the more complex class is found in the 
 "three-cornered" or "triangular exchange." We import from, 
 very much more than we export to, South America. A part of 
 the debit balance though possibly not the larger part at the
 
 294 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 present time is settled by the transmission of London drafts to 
 our South American creditors, who can use them advantageously 
 in the settlement of their debts in Europe. London thus "clears" 
 for the world as New York "clears" for America and Paris for 
 France. Just as the net balance of our foreign trade is struck in 
 New York, so final international balances are cleared or settled 
 in London, although London's preeminence in international ex- 
 change is now not so striking as it has been in the past. 
 
 The question next arises how the price or rate of exchange is 
 determined. The factors controlling the price or rate of exchange 
 are as numerous and as difficult to trace as the influences which 
 affect the price of any economic good of world-wide bargain and 
 sale. However, to facilitate discussion, we may classify them as: 
 (a) the amount of pure gold in the monetary units which are to be 
 exchanged, (6) the cost of shipping gold, and (c) "general credit 
 conditions." 
 
 An English pound sterling contains as much fine gold as 4.866 
 American dollars, and when exactly this amount must be paid in 
 New York for a draft or order for one pound payable in London, 
 exchange is said to be at par. Sterling exchange and German 
 exchange are usually quoted in dollars and cents, i.e. the amount 
 of American money required to buy one pound or four marks 
 respectively. Consequently, they rise or become dear when ex- 
 change mounts above par. French exchange, on the contrary, 
 is usually quoted in francs, the number of francs purchasable 
 with one dollar; and it is consequently cheap when above par and 
 dear when below par. Exchange between the United States and 
 countries with silver or paper standards lack the steadying in- 
 fluence of a par determined by the actual mass of fine gold in the 
 respective standards of value, and hence fluctuates much more 
 than exchange between countries on a gold basis. In order to be 
 as brief and clear as possible, the following discussion will be con- 
 fined to exchange between countries on a gold basis. 
 
 Fluctuations in the rate of exchange depend upon the "general 
 credit conditions " mentioned above, but it is plain that upper and 
 lower limits to these variations are established by the actual cost 
 of shipping gold. Suppose, for a moment, that it costs three cents
 
 2 95 
 
 to transport $4.866 worth of gold bullion between New York and 
 London. Except under unusual circumstances, then, sterling 
 exchange cannot rise above $4.896, nor fall below $4.836. These 
 limits are frequently spoken of as the "gold points," "specie 
 points," "shipping points," or "export and import points"; and 
 it is necessary to mention them because of their frequent employ- 
 ment in discussions of foreign exchange. But they are usually 
 defined in much too definite terms. The cost of shipping gold 
 varies with the size of the shipment, with freight, insurance, and 
 interest rates, and in some degree with the steamer and the season 
 of the year. Furthermore, gold is so important as the basis of 
 bank credit in all parts of the world, that it is frequently imported 
 regardless of the rate of exchange. During the war between 
 Russia and Japan, for instance, the Bank of France imported 
 large quantities of American gold in this semiarbitrary way in 
 order to protect reserves. The "gold points," then, while in one 
 sense very real, represent extreme limits and are in themselves 
 variable. 
 
 Within these extreme limits set by the cost of shipping gold, 
 the rate of exchange varies according to general credit conditions, 
 i.e. with the supply of and demand for bills of exchange, with 
 interest rates here and abroad, and the innumerable forces which 
 influence interest rates. Suppose, for instance, that our imports 
 of merchandise in a given season greatly exceed our exports of 
 merchandise. The demand for bills on London would greatly 
 exceed the supply of bills against London, and the price of sterling 
 exchange would rise very high if no other factors were involved. 
 But it may happen at the same time that interest rates in New 
 York are higher than in London, and under these circumstances 
 our foreign creditors may prefer to lend their balances in New 
 York in order to earn the high rate of interest obtaining there. 
 The placing of these loans in New York will in turn reduce the 
 demand for foreign exchange, and thus moderate both the interest 
 rate and the rate of exchange. 
 
 This interaction of the domestic and the international money 
 markets gives rise to a number of complex transactions which can 
 only be suggested here. In discussing the sale of foreign exchange
 
 296 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 on page 293 above, American bankers were described as drawing 
 against credit balances which they had built up abroad. Some 
 bankers' bills, however, the so-called " finance bills," are drawn 
 in excess of the foreign balances, and thus represent borrowings 
 abroad. Finance bills are used (a) to tide over the time before a 
 plentiful supply of documentary bills is available; and, (ft) to 
 take advantage of low discount rates abroad, e.g. in London, by 
 borrowing in London and lending the proceeds in New York. 
 Under the latter circumstances, finance bills payable in London 
 at sixty or ninety days are sold in large quantities in New York, 
 the sellers commonly covering their risk by the purchase of future 
 drafts calling for the payment of the same amounts in London at 
 the dates when the bills mature. The finance bill is thus one of 
 many credit instruments used to bring the loanable funds of the 
 world to the market where they will command the highest rate of 
 interest; and it is hardly necessary to add that it assumes at times 
 a highly speculative character. " Bankers sometimes purchase 
 outright entire new issues of securities from corporations with 
 proceeds obtained by the issue of finance bills, sell the securities 
 to investors during the currency of the finance bills, and apply the 
 proceeds realized through the sale of the securities to the payment 
 of the bills at maturity." 1 
 
 Regulation of the Gold Supply. We may now return to the 
 general topic of trade regulation, from which we digressed in 
 order to consider the fundamental principles of foreign exchange. 
 Historically, it will be remembered, many of the most important 
 restrictions of trade have had as their object the regulation of the 
 gold supply. And the movement of gold is still of great interest 
 to the world of high finance because of the dependence of the 
 volume of bank credits upon the gold reserves of the banks. But 
 the preceding discussion would seem to make it clear that, ordi- 
 narily, there is little that the government can do, or needs to do, 
 in the way of regulating the supply of gold. Through interna- 
 tional trade and foreign exchange, the gold supply of the world 
 is automatically distributed among the countries which need gold, 
 in accordance with the intensity of their respective demands. 
 
 1 Margraff, International Exchange, p. 41.
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 297 
 
 In ordinary or normal times, the interest rate is the most power- 
 ful of the many influences which control the distribution of the 
 gold supply. International banking houses keep funds in both 
 the United States and Europe, and they are constantly shifting 
 their money to the market in which it will earn the highest rate of 
 interest. The means employed to move their funds may vary, as 
 has been explained, all the way from the simple sale of foreign 
 exchange to the actual importation of gold. So great is the influ- 
 ence exercised by the rate of interest over the gold supply that the 
 Bank of England usually finds it necessary to do nothing more 
 than raise its discount rate when it desires to attract gold to Eng- 
 land or discourage its exportation. 
 
 The ordinary price level, that is, of merchandise, also exercises 
 a great influence upon the rate of exchange and the movement of 
 gold. When prices abroad are high compared with American 
 prices, foreign countries increase their purchases, the supply of 
 American bills increases, sterling exchange falls, and if it goes low 
 enough, may cause the shipment of gold to this country. Such a 
 condition of affairs, for instance, is likely to occur in the autumn 
 months, when large exportations of American cotton, wheat, and 
 agricultural products create a plethora of bills on London, and, 
 other things being equal, depress the price of sterling exchange. 
 
 There can be no doubt, then, that the price level does influence 
 the movement of gold. Whether the gold movement influences 
 prices, however, is disputed. Some opponents of the so-called 
 " quantity theory " of money hold that it does not, maintaining 
 that before a drain of gold, for instance, could raise prices, it 
 would so elevate the interest rate that the drain would be checked 
 and gold be brought back. In their view, the interest rate acts 
 as a safety valve, through whose variations any protracted gold 
 movement which threatens to disturb the price level is checked and 
 reversed before it acquires the momentum requisite to accom- 
 plish the larger task. Without attempting to decide the question, 
 we may be sure at least of this relevant conclusion: that if the 
 movement of gold continued indefinitely, prices would unques- 
 tionably be affected. 
 
 The gold supply thus adjusts itself automatically to the respec-
 
 298 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tive demands of the various districts of the world. This truth 
 is important because it establishes a prima facie presumption 
 against laws or policies which interfere with the normal distri- 
 bution of the precious metals. This presumption is only an initial 
 one, however. It does not follow that " artificial " interference 
 with the distribution of the gold supply is never warranted. In 
 times of war, panic, or severe financial stringency, extraordinary 
 expedients for obtaining gold are sometimes used which, like the 
 heroic remedies employed in desperate illness, are necessitated by 
 the exigencies of the situation. In the undignified scramble for 
 gold which often attends a panic, the country or the individual 
 who stands aloof and waits for the normal laws of distribution to 
 bring him " his " share of the gold supply, may have cause to 
 regret his inaction. Nevertheless, it is true that such expedients, 
 like strong drugs, are to be used with the greatest caution. They 
 are frequently employed when the situation does not demand 
 them, their use tends to become a fixed habit, and they seldom 
 accomplish more than the postponement of the crisis. 
 
 An expedient of the kind described was employed by Mr. 
 Shaw, then Secretary of the Treasury, in the spring of 1906. 
 The following critical account of the action of the Secretary 
 may be unjust to him, for it must be remembered that the financial 
 stringency of the time threatened to become dangerous; but it 
 illustrates in a striking way the subtle modern devices sometimes 
 used to increase the supply of gold. 
 
 "On April 14 it was officially announced for the first time, that the Sec- 
 retary would allow any depositary bank which engaged to import gold to 
 anticipate the arrival of the gold by withdrawing a like amount in cash from 
 the Treasury upon pledge of saving-bank collateral as security. The sum 
 so withdrawn was to be regarded as a temporary loan, and to be returned to 
 the Treasury as soon as the gold arrived. In providing such an arrangement, 
 Mr. Shaw virtually reduced the cost of importing gold by the amount of 
 interest during transit, and raised by so much the 'gold import point.' In 
 other words, he endeavored to make it profitable for the depositary bank, 
 to import gold without waiting for sterling exchange to fall to the normal 
 'gold point.' . . . In accomplishing this, Mr. Shaw, temporarily eliminated, 
 so far as the national banks were concerned, one item of expense in their 
 foreign exchange operations. He gave them an advantage, for the time being, 
 over all other firms engaged in the same business; and his action naturally
 
 INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 299 
 
 excited criticism among the private bankers who found themselves discrimi- 
 nated against. Critics also attacked his method of announcing his decision. 
 It appeared that several days before the public or the other banks were 
 informed of his intention, Mr. Shaw had seen fit to make private arrangements 
 with two New York banks for gold imports under the plan . . . Nor was 
 hostile criticism mitigated by the general publication at this moment of the fact, 
 which had not been widely known before, that one of these same banks had 
 been favored by the Treasury for several weeks, and possibly months, pre- 
 ceding, with virtually the same privilege under a different guise. This had 
 been accomplished by allowing the bank in question to count as part of its 
 reserve its importations of gold during their period of transit to New York. 
 The imported gold had thus been made practically available as a basis for 
 loans from the moment of its purchase abroad, and the item of time cost in 
 such imports had been as completely eliminated as under the subsequently 
 adopted plan. . . . His [Secretary Shaw's] statement issued at the time 
 seemed to indicate that, in his opinion, the natural movement of gold was 
 toward this country, but that the flow was being lured to other markets 
 by the practices of European banks. He apparently hoped to overcome what 
 he took to be an artificial diversion of gold from the United States by adopting, 
 through the agency of the Treasury, measures similar to those which were 
 being employed by the French and German central banks." * 
 
 1 A. P. Andrew, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August, 1907, pp. 544-546. 
 (For Questions and References, see the following chapter.)
 
 CHAPTER XVIII 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 
 
 WE are now in a position to review intelligibly the pros and 
 cons of the modern tariff controversy. Because of the limitations 
 of space, it will be desirable to confine the discussion almost 
 wholly to American conditions, although most of the arguments 
 are applicable to other countries as well. 
 
 The Case for Protection. (i) One of the most captivating 
 arguments for protection is the assertion that it promotes nation- 
 alism, which is held to be a good thing. Domestic trade, it is 
 claimed, draws the citizens of a country together, while international 
 trade is cosmopolitan and tends to their separation. Upon the 
 creation of our federal government, state tariffs were abolished 
 and their place taken by a national tariff designed partly to pro- 
 tect the whole of the country against the rest of the world. The 
 introduction of national protection thus went hand in hand with 
 the promotion of internal free trade; and Professor Schmoller 
 even maintains the general thesis that, historically, this double 
 process of internal abolition and external extension of tariffs 
 marks the formation of new states, particularly federal states. 
 Protection against foreign competition, he asserts, is thus his- 
 torically coincident with the enfranchisement of internal trade; 
 and has as its main object the creation of a strong national eco- 
 nomic unity, without which permanent political unity, he thinks, 
 is impossible. 
 
 (2) Government should, the protectionists say, foster infant 
 industries in order to develop our natural resources and to pro- 
 duce diversity in industrial pursuits. It is admitted that protec- 
 tion is temporarily expensive, but so is the prohibition of child 
 labor temporarily expensive. We prevent children from earning 
 
 300 

 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 301 
 
 a little while they are young in order that they may earn more 
 when they are old. For the same reasons trades unions rightfully 
 insist that apprentices shall be given a broad knowledge of the 
 trade they are learning, although it is more profitable for the em- 
 ployer to have them specialize early in some narrow branch of 
 the work. So, similarly, free trade prevents a nation from special- 
 izing too exclusively in its undeveloped stage, in order that it may 
 the sooner arrive at industrial manhood. 
 
 Economists have generally admitted that there is a certain 
 amount of truth in this argument. If an industry gets an early 
 start in a given district, this locality is likely to retain its advan- 
 tage because of the concentration there of capital and labor ac- 
 quainted with the requirements and possibilities of the industry. 
 Thus, 69.3 per cent of all the clocks manufactured in this country 
 are made in Connecticut, for no other reasons that one can see 
 than those suggested in the explanatory phrase "the momen- 
 tum acquired by an early start." And this localization of indus- 
 try is artificially fostered by the habit, common to exporters all 
 over the world, of selling abroad more cheaply than at home. 
 The export trade seems to be universally coddled. Of course, 
 such localized industries can be maintained only when the cost 
 of transporting the article is small; and when other districts do 
 not possess unusual natural advantages in the way of accessibility 
 to superior raw material, power, or skilled labor. The census 
 studies in the localization of domestic industries l seem to indicate 
 that while the industrial inertia of which we have been speaking 
 is an important factor, it is not so important as the opposing 
 forces making for territorial diffusion of industry. 
 
 A most interesting illustration of an attempt to crush the " infant indus- 
 tries " of a competing nation is found in the effort of English manufacturers, 
 after the War of 1812, to recover the American market of which they had been 
 temporarily deprived by the long period of non-intercourse. "English 
 manufacturers, eager to regain control of the lost markets, sent in shiploads 
 of cotton and woolens and iron manufactures, which they offered on the most 
 liberal terms to their agents in this country. The goods were taken on credit 
 and disposed of at auction. The object was to undersell at any cost, and thus 
 
 1 Special Census Report, " Manufactures," 1905, Part I, p. cclx. Cf. also, 
 Twelfth Census, " Manufactures," Part I, pp. cclx-codv.
 
 3 02 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 break down the infant industries. Lord Brougham justified the speculative 
 character of this trade on the ground that ' it was well worth while to incur 
 a loss upon the first exportation, in order, by the glut, to stifle in the cradle 
 those rising manufactures in the United States which the war had forced into 
 existence contrary to the natural course of things.' " ' 
 
 (3) Closely connected with the preceding arguments is a de- 
 fense of protection based upon grounds of war and military neces- 
 sity. Industrial independence, it is asserted, prepares a nation 
 better for international war. There is unquestionably a great 
 deal of truth in the argument. Certainly a wise nation will see 
 to it that within its boundaries factories exist which can manu- 
 facture arms and all the necessary munitions of war. But success 
 in war is not dependent upon arms and ammunitions alone. There 
 must be a plentiful supply of money, and whatever use may be 
 made of credit, enormous amounts of money must be raised by 
 taxation. 2 But the source of taxation is a flourishing condition 
 of private industry; and the industry of the average nation de- 
 pendent upon international trade cannot flourish in times of war. 
 The failure of the South in the Civil War was very largely due 
 to her industrial dependence upon the cotton export trade. A 
 sufficient diversification of industry to prevent industrial paralysis 
 in times of war is, we believe, manifestly desirable. 
 
 (4) The home market argument for protection naturally fol- 
 lows. Much that is said in defense of this claim is childish or 
 silly. One distinguished American economist seriously main- 
 tained that a country can remain permanently prosperous only 
 on condition that what is taken from the soil shall be returned in 
 manure and other kinds of fertilizers, and that this will be accom- 
 plished only when the products of the soil are consumed at home. 
 A much stronger application of the argument, however, is found 
 in the assertion that the home market is superior because it is a 
 surer market. A foreign market is usually a precarious market. 
 It is likely to be closed by war or by capricious changes in tariff 
 policy. Protection is unquestionably expensive to the country 
 
 1 Coman, Industrial History of the United States, p. 185. 
 
 8 For a classic explanation of the dependence of both public credit and taxation 
 upon a flourishing condition of private business in times of war, see Public Debts. 
 by Henry C. Adams.
 
 PROTECTION AN 7 D FREE TRADE 
 
 303 
 
 that protects, but it is worth paying something to keep industries 
 in continuous operation. 
 
 (5) This brings us to the argument against "dumping." By 
 dumping is meant the sale of products abroad at prices lower than 
 those charged at home. Dumping arises in a variety of ways. 
 Export bounties may be granted by the home country for the spe- 
 cific purpose of encouraging foreign trade; or a monopoly may 
 find it profitable to dispose of a surplus abroad at prices which 
 would be needlessly low in the highly protected home country; 
 and, indeed, there is good reason to believe that many manufac- 
 turers for the export trade make it a practice to sell abroad at 
 unusually low prices whenever they believe that their foreign 
 market is threatened. As was stated above, the custom of "cod- 
 dling" the export trade seems to be very general. 
 
 Now if the reduction of prices were permanent, the country in 
 which the products are dumped would have no real cause for com- 
 plaint. On the contrary, it might logically regard itself as the 
 beneficiary of the costly bounties of the other nation. But real 
 dumping is not, and in the nature of things cannot be, permanent. 
 So far as it may be said to have a rational object, it aims to sup- 
 press competing industries by selling temporarily below cost; and 
 when those industries are forced out of business, prices will be 
 raised. So true is this that economists have generally indorsed 
 import taxes and other temperate retaliatory measures designed to 
 abolish dumping. Canada, for instance, has authorized the levy 
 in such cases of a special dumping duty "equal to the difference 
 between the selling price of the article for export and the fair 
 market value thereof for home consumption." A few years ago 
 the beet-sugar industry of France and Germany was so stimu- 
 lated by bounties that even England, the principal dumping 
 ground of the product, was forced to threaten reprisals in the shape 
 of countervailing import duties. England's resolute attitude, it 
 may be added, led finally to the virtual abolition of sugar bounties 
 at the International Sugar Conference of 1903. In general, there 
 seems to be ample justification for protective duties that are hon- 
 estly used to ward off destructive attacks upon home industries 
 which, if subjected only to legitimate competition, would be able
 
 304 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 to maintain themselves in the long run. It is evident that we 
 have here returned to the substratum of truth contained in the 
 infant industry and home market arguments. 
 
 Dumping has been more productive of arguments against protection than 
 of arguments for protection, in the United States; and the opponents of pro- 
 tection have laid great emphasis upon the fact that many articles of American 
 manufacture are sold abroad more cheaply than at home. That this is a fact 
 is now generally admitted. But the protectionists maintain that most of this 
 can be explained by the rebates allowed to American exporters under our 
 drawback laws. Ex-Secretary of the Treasury Shaw estimates that in 1906, 
 owing to these drawbacks, about $140,000,000 of American manufactures 
 might have been legitimately sold abroad at less than domestic prices. 1 
 
 (6) Intimately related to the arguments which we have been 
 considering is the claim that the distribution of labor and capital 
 of a free-trade nation is subject to the control, and indeed, one 
 may say, to the whim and caprice of foreign nations. Industries 
 differ in their effect upon the physique and character of the people 
 who pursue them. The builder, the skilled engineer, the electrical 
 worker, are benefited intellectually, physically, and morally by 
 their occupations. But the tailor, the maker of ready-made cloth- 
 ing, and the sweat-shop worker are probably harmed rather than 
 elevated by the nature of their employment. Now if foreign na- 
 tions subsidize by protection and bounty the desirable industries, 
 they may leave to the free-trade nation only those industries which 
 the protected nations do not wish to maintain. 
 
 (7) Finally, protectionists appeal to the wage-earning classes 
 with the argument that protection increases wages by diversify- 
 ing industry and thus stimulating the demand for labor. Indeed 
 the typical protectionist goes farther than this, and maintains that 
 every American industry is entitled to an amount of protection 
 equal to the difference between the wages which it pays and the 
 wages paid by its most efficient foreign competitor. The latter variety 
 of this argument seems to be plainly absurd, or at least obviously 
 inconsistent with the initial assertion that protection raises wages. 
 For, taken together, and they are frequently advanced in com- 
 pany, they result in this magnificently cumulative plea for 
 ever increasing tariffs: protection raises wages, but high wages 
 
 1 Leslie M. Shaw, Current Issues, Chap. XXI.
 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 
 
 305 
 
 put the American manufacturer at a disadvantage in competing 
 with foreign producers, and the home producer must be pro- 
 tected to the extent of the difference in wages, therefore every 
 advance in protective duties laid for the benefit of the wage earner 
 must be accompanied by an additional advance for the benefit of 
 the manufacturer, and so ad infinitum. 
 
 Arguments of Free Traders. In the first place, we may dis- 
 miss a number of arguments which are so extreme as to weaken 
 rather than strengthen the cause of free trade, (i) For instance, 
 it is frequently alleged that protective tariffs violate the assumed 
 natural right of every man to buy his goods where he will and sell 
 his products wherever he sees fit, untrammeled by human laws. 
 The futility of arguments based upon an assumption of natural 
 rights has been sufficiently exposed elsewhere, and needs no elabo- 
 ration at this point. 
 
 (2) It has also been claimed that protective tariffs in the United 
 States are unconstitutional, but this argument is idle; it would be 
 most unfortunate and anomalous if nowhere in our country were 
 lodged the power to pass such regulations regarding international 
 commerce as might appear to be required for the promotion of 
 the public welfare. Furthermore, the charge of unconstitution- 
 ally does not correspond to the opinion of our best jurists, and it 
 is very certain that we shall never see a supreme court in the 
 United States which will venture to pronounce protectionism 
 unconstitutional. 
 
 (3) In a similar vein protectionism has been called socialism, 
 but this epithet is so generally applied to whatever a person in- 
 competent to argue a cause does not like that it will scarcely ter- 
 rify any one. 
 
 The really able arguments of free traders are those which aim 
 to show either that protection actually does positive harm, or that 
 it fails to accomplish its ends, or that those ends may be better 
 accomplished without protection. 
 
 (4) The natural starting point of the free-trade argument, and 
 the goal to which it inevitably returns is the theory of compara- 
 tive costs laid down on page 285, the proposition that, so long as 
 there are relative, not necessarily absolute, differences in the cost
 
 306 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of producing cheaply portable articles in various countries of the 
 world, so long will there be international trade in those articles. 
 Protective tariffs, therefore, merely divert capital and labor from 
 intrinsically more productive to intrinsically less productive in- 
 dustries. To revert to our simile of the lawyer and his stenog- 
 rapher, protection aims to induce the lawyer to write his own 
 letters, on the general grounds that lawyers are more intelligent 
 people than stenographers, and if sufficient encouragement be 
 held out to them they may, in the course of time, be educated up 
 to the point of operating their own typewriting machines better 
 than the stenographers whom they have previously hired. 
 
 Temperate advocates of "freer trade" do not contend that this 
 law of comparative costs demonstrates the desirability of complete 
 free trade under all circumstances. They admit that it may occa- 
 sionally be profitable for a country to pay enormous bounties 
 this is what protection amounts to for the development of cer- 
 tain industries. But they do contend that it establishes free 
 trade as the general rule, every departure from which should re- 
 quire the most positive justification. More particularly, they 
 hold, that at the present time, after a century of industrial devel- 
 opment that obviates any military necessity for a further diversifica- 
 tion of industry, capital and labor should be freely allowed to 
 take themselves to those employments in which they can reap the 
 largest natural reward, a reward, that is to say, which is not arti- 
 ficially enhanced by subsidies wrung from the general body of 
 consumers. 
 
 (5) Moreover, it is not clear that protection is necessary to di- 
 versify industry in a country with such varied natural resources as 
 the United States. The claims of the protectionists at this point 
 may be tested by examining conditions within the wide borders 
 of our own country, within which trade is wholly free. Now, if 
 protection were necessary to foster infant industries and bring 
 them to maturity, the manufacturing industries of this country 
 would still be concentrated in the northern states of the Atlantic 
 seaboard where they first gained a foothold. But they have not 
 been so confined. The early establishment of the textile indus- 
 tries in New England has not prevented their recent development
 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 307 
 
 in the South. Indeed, the so-called "center of manufactures" 
 moved steadily west from south-central Pennsylvania in 1850 to 
 central Ohio in 1900; and the increase, at the present time, is 
 much more rapid in the South and West than in older sections of 
 the country. Internal free trade has not prevented the diversifi- 
 cation of industry in the United States, and has not delayed it 
 longer than was desirable. For who shall say that the Dakotas 
 and other typical agricultural states of the Union have greatly 
 suffered from the absence of grimy factory towns and the slums 
 which almost inevitably accompany them? 
 
 (6) The inevitable spread of manufactures throughout the 
 United States suggests the essential weakness of the home market 
 argument. International trade expands just as inevitably as the 
 manufacturing area. It might be desirable to confine domestic 
 producers to the more certain home market, which cannot be de- 
 stroyed by tariff wars or international complications. But, as a 
 matter of fact, home producers will seek foreign markets, and the 
 nation that sells abroad must buy abroad. Since the Civil War we 
 have protected home producers with extremely high tariffs. But 
 in the last twenty-five years our foreign trade has increased at a 
 rate unequaled by any of the other great commercial countries 
 of the world. 1 Protective tariffs can cripple and harass and dis- 
 tract foreign trade, but they cannot permanently suppress it. No 
 tariff can make the costs of producing all the articles common to 
 commerce precisely proportional in all quarters of the globe. 
 
 (7) The protectionistic appeal to the wage earner seems par- 
 ticularly inconclusive. One reason for distrusting it is the double- 
 faced way in which it is manipulated to suit the particular re- 
 quirements of time and place. France wants protection in order 
 to protect her low-paid workmen against the greater skill and 
 efficiency of America's highly paid workers. The United States, 
 on the other hand, must have protection in order to shield her 
 highly paid employees from competition with the "pauper labor 
 of Europe." When first used in the United States, the argument 
 was that wages were already so high in this country as compared 
 
 1 Special Reports of the Census Office, "Manufactures," 1905, Part I, p. ccc. 
 The specific period referred to is the twenty-five years, 1880-1905.
 
 308 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 with England, that it was impossible for manufacturers in this 
 country to pay the American rates and continue to compete with 
 English manufacturers. Later, cause and effect, as related in the 
 earlier syllogism, were reversed, and it was asserted that the high 
 wages in this country were due to protection, from which it 
 followed naturally that in order to raise wages higher, still more 
 protection would have to be given. 
 
 We cannot arrive at any useful conclusions concerning wages, 
 however, without considering the efficiency of labor and the pro- 
 ductivity or favorableness of the environment in which the laborer 
 works. The reason why American labor may receive higher 
 wages and yet have nothing to fear from the competition of less 
 highly paid workmen in Europe is found in the greater produc- 
 tivity of American labor (though this greater productivity may 
 depend more upon the natural wealth of this country than upon 
 any innate technical superiority of the American workmen). The 
 average American workman is in no more danger from the goods 
 produced by the "pauper labor" of Europe than the highly paid 
 workman of Montana is threatened by the products of his less 
 remunerated fellow- workmen of New England and the South. 
 Labor competes with labor, not with commodities. Consequently, 
 if it is really desired to protect labor, the logical way would be to 
 place a tax on imported labor, or by other measures to reduce 
 immigration. If this were done, those who desire labor would be 
 obliged to pay heavily for it, as actually happened in England 
 after the "Black Death" in the fourteenth century had killed off 
 a large part of the laboring population. Indeed, if our tariff 
 makers are sincerely anxious to benefit labor, they should, after 
 rendering labor scarce and dear by restricting immigration, en- 
 courage the importation of such commodities as are consumed 
 primarily by wage earners, in order that labor may secure an 
 abundance of them cheaply. 
 
 No intelligent free trader would deny that there are now dependent upon 
 protection many industries which pay high wages, nor that the sudden aboli- 
 tion of protection would throw many wage earners out of work. Their con- 
 tention in the first case is merely that by taxation and by diverting capital 
 and labor into naturally unproductive industries, protection lowers the general
 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 
 
 309 
 
 level of real wages. Their reply to the second point is that protection affects 
 the industrial organism much as the alcoholic habit affects the human organ- 
 ism. To abandon the habit suddenly would certainly be painful and prob- 
 ably dangerous but this is sufficient reason neither for increasing the dram 
 nor delaying the gradual abandonment of the habit. 
 
 (8) Turning to the fiscal aspects of the question, the free trader 
 asserts that there is little or nothing to be said in favor of protection. 
 The protective import duty, as compared with the import duty "for 
 revenue only," is a poor tax. It is uncertain and viciously vari- 
 able, and in the great majority of cases is borne by the home 
 consumer. To the extent that it does not prevent importation it 
 affords no protection; and in so far as it does protect, it yields no 
 revenue to the government. If it raises the price of the article upon 
 which it is levied, however, the increase constitutes a tax upon one 
 class of society the consumer for the benefit of another class 
 the producers of the article. One authority, perhaps the fore- 
 most authority, upon the American tariff problem, estimates that 
 the present tariff upon sugar results in an annual tax upon Ameri- 
 can consumers of $101,000,000, of which $52,400,000 go into the 
 treasury and $48,600,000 into the hands of sugar producers, prin- 
 cipally resident in Hawaii, Porto Rico, and Cuba. 1 
 
 In answer to this charge that protection involves the taxation of 
 one class for the benefit of another class, it is not sufficient to 
 reply that everybody is free to take advantage of the subsidy and 
 engage in a protected industry. Everybody is not free to estab- 
 lish a rolling mill or a silk factory or a tin-plate plant. Protection 
 means the taxation of the less acute, the less enterprising, the less 
 educated and the poorer classes in order to create additional com- 
 mercial opportunities for the abler, wealthier, and better-educated 
 classes, thus reversing the whole spirit of modern taxation which 
 contemplates so far as it may be done without danger rather 
 the taxation of the rich for the assistance of the poor than the 
 taxation of the poor for the benefit of the rich. It is not implied, 
 of course, that protection involves class legislation of an unlawful 
 character, nor that taxes are collected from one class and handed 
 over in cold cash to the members of another class. The point 
 
 1 Professor F. W. Taussig, in the Atlantic Monthly for March, 1908, p. 343.
 
 310 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 turns upon the relative ability of the various social classes to take 
 advantage of artificial opportunities created by the state at enor- 
 mous expense to all. 
 
 (9) This brings us naturally to the ethical criticism of protection, 
 the charge that by making the temporary prosperity of influential 
 classes dependent upon government bounty, protection encour- 
 ages those classes to exert a demoralizing pressure upon federal 
 legislation. So great is the stake of private interests in tariff legis- 
 lation, that systematic lobbying, log rolling, and corruption of the 
 voter follow as inevitable consequences. The beneficiary of the 
 tariff sacrifices his disinterested convictions concerning the general 
 welfare, in order to preserve his own little subsidy from the gov- 
 ernment. Neither the citizen nor the legislator can vote purely, 
 when his pocketbook is so vitally affected. Even if we admit 
 what is probably true, that protection has resulted in comparatively 
 little direct bribery of legislators, there seems no escape from the 
 conclusion that it creates a kind of interest in legislation which 
 is inherently dangerous and exceedingly difficult to keep within 
 legitimate bounds. And as the manufacturing industries of the 
 country fall more and more into the hands of large corporations 
 and trusts, the possibilities of political corruption become more 
 and more sinister, while the character of the chief beneficiaries of 
 protection make them more and more undeserving of the bounties 
 which they receive. 
 
 (10) Finally, it is alleged that protection fosters monopolies by 
 shutting off international competition. This contention forms the 
 subject-matter of a particularly heated dispute, and the exact ex- 
 tent to which the charge is true cannot be determined at this time. 
 Certain modifications of the more extreme charge, however, are 
 hardly open to question. Protectionists confessedly take it for 
 granted that if foreign competition is shut off or lessened, home 
 producers will still compete. Nevertheless, highly protective du- 
 ties are still levied upon commodities whose manufacture in the 
 United States has fallen under the substantial control of monopo- 
 lies. It is furthermore admitted that such monopolies frequently 
 sell their products at lower prices in foreign countries than in the 
 United States; while it is impossible to deny that whether the
 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 311 
 
 monopoly was created by protection or not the abolition of the 
 duties, by giving foreign producers a chance to compete in this 
 country, would tend to reduce prices, and thus give the American 
 public a valuable ally in their struggle against monopoly. The 
 tariff therefore may or may not be the mother of trusts, but it 
 unquestionably deprives the American people of a strong weapon 
 against the trusts. 
 
 Some General Considerations. Before attempting to sum up 
 the preceding arguments and strike a practical working balance, 
 it is necessary to call attention to certain general considerations 
 which have not figured in the foregoing "starched procession" of 
 pros and cons. In the first place, it is necessary to remember that 
 the federal government must secure a large revenue from tariff 
 duties, and that in consequence the question which we are dis- 
 cussing is not one of protection versus free trade, but of protection 
 versus freer trade. In the second place, the economic importance 
 of the whole controversy has unquestionably been exaggerated. 
 We find a country like England prosperous under free trade; we 
 find countries like France and the United States prosperous under 
 protection. It is of real but not of vital importance. Our inter- 
 nal trade vastly exceeds our foreign trade in every way. The 
 domestic trade of the Mississippi Valley alone is far greater than 
 our entire foreign commerce. In the third place, the American 
 tariff is a historical growth, and bad as it may be in many respects 
 it has taken deep root. During the last century it has become 
 part of our life, and cannot be suddenly eradicated with impunity. 
 If it is true that American labor would be better off without it, it 
 does not follow that it ought to be removed suddenly in the inter- 
 ests of American labor. If the industrial growth is abnormal, it 
 is none the less true that adjustment to normal conditions is a 
 painful process and should be conducted cautiously. Displace- 
 ments of labor and capital cause suffering and loss, and it is clear 
 that any reform of the tariff must be conservative and careful, 
 a movement toward freer trade, not the sudden withdrawal of 
 protection. 
 
 Conclusions. Most of the arguments enumerated above, both 
 for and against protection, contain a measure of truth. Historic-
 
 312 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ally, we believe that protection was inevitable in the United 
 States, and in the early period of the country's development, bene- 
 ficial. During the three great wars which seriously threatened the 
 stability of this country, many new industries sprang up which, 
 upon the cessation of war and the resumption of international 
 trade, were seriously threatened by foreign competition. Many 
 of these industries were so suited to our soil and our people that 
 only a short period of protection was needed to make them self- 
 supporting. Under the circumstances it would have been unwise 
 to permit the sacrifice of the capital invested in these industries; 
 and whether it would have been unwise or not, human nature is 
 such that the needed protection was sure to be granted. In short, 
 there is a large measure of real truth in the infant industry argu- 
 ment. 
 
 Circumstances, however, have radically changed in the last few 
 decades. Our quondam infant industries have, for the most part, 
 attained a very vigorous maturity, and in some instances have 
 become belligerent and prone to monopolistic bullying; our manu- 
 factures have become sufficiently diversified to remove all danger 
 of industrial collapse in time of war; and, above all, we are rapidly 
 entering the economic stage in which, according to the ablest ex- 
 ponent of protection that economic science has ever known, 
 Frederick List, protection is a hindrance rather than a help. 
 That is to say, we are rapidly building up an extensive export 
 trade in manufactured articles; year by year raw materials con- 
 stitute a larger proportion of our imports and a smaller propor- 
 tion of our exports; and we have already become the greatest 
 exporting country of the world. All this means that in the near 
 future our manufacturers themselves will look with kindlier eyes 
 upon the withdrawal of the protection they do not need, which in 
 fact actually increases the cost of some of their raw materials, 
 and incites foreign governments to retaliatory taxation upon goods 
 imported from the United States. Our growing export trade will 
 itself bring a wider appreciation of those fundamental principles 
 which have led economists, with but few exceptions, to condemn 
 protection as a permanent policy applicable to all stages of eco- 
 nomic development.
 
 PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. What is meant by the law of comparative costs? Is the American 
 custom of importing the finer textile fabrics and manufacturing the coarser 
 ones an effect of this law ? 
 
 2. In the illustrative case cited on page 285, would America confine herself 
 wholly, or only chiefly, to the production of flour ? Would the fact that some 
 cloth was produced in America, and some flour in Holland, affect the validity 
 of the law of comparative costs ? 
 
 3. If a widow needs money so badly that she is willing to pay 200 per 
 cent a year for its use, why is it wrong for a money lender to charge this rate ? 
 
 4. What is the real nature of the balance of trade ? Does our excess of 
 exports (merchandise) mean that we are paying off our foreign indebtedness, 
 or merely that we are paying interest on our foreign indebtedness? 
 
 5. In what respects does foreign exchange differ from exchange between 
 two American cities ? 
 
 6. What are the principal influences which affect the rate of exchange ? 
 
 7. Is the gold supply distributed according to the needs or the respective 
 demands of the various countries ? Are needs and demands in this connection 
 identical ? 
 
 8. Mention as many methods as you can by which governments have 
 endeavored to increase the supply of gold. 
 
 9. To what extent is the infant industry argument true? The home- 
 market argument? The argument against "dumping"? 
 
 10. In what form was the wages argument first employed in the United 
 States? In what does its essential error consist? 
 
 LITERATURE 
 
 ASHLEY, PERCY. Modern Tariff History. 
 
 ASHLEY, W. J. Tariff Problems. 
 
 BASTABLE, C. F. TJteory of International Trade. 
 
 BROOKS, H. K. Foreign Exchange Text-Book. 
 
 CLARE, GEORGE. Tim ABC of the Foreign Exchanges; The Money Market 
 
 Primer. 
 
 DAY, CLIVE. History of Commerce. 
 ELY, R. T. Problems of To-day. Chaps. I-XV. 
 FISK, G. M. International Commercial Policies. 
 GIFFEN, ROBERT. The Use of Export and Import Statistics; and Economic 
 
 Inquiries and Studies, Vol. I, Chap. IX. 
 GEORGE, HENRY. Protection or Free Trade. 
 GOSCHEN, G. J. Theory of the Foreign Exchanges. 
 LAUGHLIN, J. L. The Principles of Money. Chap. X, pp. 336-370. 
 MARGRAFF, A. W. International Exchange.
 
 314 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 PATTEN, S. N. The Economic Basis of Protection. 
 
 PRATT, S. S. The Work of Wall Street. 
 
 RABBENO, V. The American Commercial Policy. 
 
 STANWOOD, E. American Tariff Controversies in the Nineteenth Century. 
 
 SUMNER, W. G. History of Protection in the United States. 
 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Tariff History in the United States. "The Present 
 Position of the Doctrine of Free Trade," Publications of the American 
 Economic Association, Third Series, Vol. VI, pp. 29-65 ; also State 
 Papers and Speeches on the Tariff.
 
 PART V 
 DISTRIBUTION 
 
 CHAPTER XIX 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 IT has already been remarked that the production and the dis- 
 tribution of the annual income of society cannot be sharply sepa- 
 rated, and more or less has already been said about the four parts 
 into which the products of industry are usually divided; namely, 
 wages, interest, rent, and profits. The greater part of distribu- 
 tion might undoubtedly be considered under the general heading 
 "Production," but on the other hand, it is frequently asserted that 
 distribution is "the true center of all economic inquiries," and it 
 would be possible to treat nearly the whole of production from 
 the standpoint of distribution. The truth is that these old tra- 
 ditional divisions of our subject-matter indicate different points of 
 view, and on this account it seems desirable to retain them. When 
 we pass from production to distribution, we do not enter an entirely 
 new field, but we look at an old field of investigation from a new 
 point of view. 
 
 The center of interest in the practical applications of economic 
 principles has shifted from production to distribution. The mer- 
 cantilistic writers of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries were 
 primarily interested in the most efficient ways of increasing the 
 sum total of a nation's wealth. Even Adam Smith, as the title of 
 his great work, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the 
 Wealth of Nations, indicates, had chiefly in mind the same prob- 
 lem, although he emphasized the fact that the real well-being of a 
 nation consists in the well-being of the great body of its people. 
 During the past century the production of wealth has increased 
 beyond all precedent, the chief factors contributing to this result 
 
 315
 
 316 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 being the factory system, the exploitation of vast natural re- 
 sources (made possible only by modern methods of transportation) 
 and the free scope given to the initiative of the individual business 
 man. In the United States, at least, we do not feel that there are 
 any pressing problems concerning the production of wealth. Yet 
 poverty still exists, and its harsh features are thrown into sharper 
 relief by contrast with the fact that the present production of 
 wealth per capita in the United States is indisputably the highest 
 that the world has ever known. Moreover, while the social dis- 
 content arising from inequalities in the distribution of wealth is 
 a very old thing, it is only in modern times that democracy has 
 given it an adequate opportunity for formulated, organized ex- 
 pression. It is not too much to say that nearly all the economic 
 problems which are felt to press upon society to-day for solution 
 relate directly or indirectly to the distribution of wealth. 
 
 It should be noted, however, that we have to discuss under 
 the name " distribution " two different processes. The first and 
 inclusive meaning of the term is the distribution of the wealth or 
 income of society among individuals and families ; in other 
 words, the question of individual fortunes, poverty and wealth. 
 The second kind of distribution is the division of the product 
 among the different factors of production. This is not a question 
 of wealth versus poverty, but of wages versus interest, profits, 
 and rent. Of course, this kind of distribution affects the personal 
 distribution of wealth, but it is by no means the same question. 
 To explain why lots in New York City command high rents is one 
 thing; to explain why a large amount of these rents go to the As tor 
 family is another thing. In the case of wages, however, the two 
 kinds of distribution amount to about the same thing. There is 
 another sense in which the word is not used in this chapter. We 
 do not mean by distribution the moving of goods from the place 
 where they are produced to the place where they are consumed. 
 When we hear of railways or other concerns as "distributive 
 agencies," we are using the term " distribution " in a sense very 
 different from that of the technical economic term "distribution." 
 Distribution is a question of ownership, not a question of the 
 location of goods.
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 317 
 
 Distribution controlled by Existing Institutions. The statement that 
 distribution is a matter of ownership suggests at once the relation of private 
 property to distribution. Individual wealth is, fundamentally, a sum of 
 property rights. Every extension of property rights by society, as, for ex- 
 ample, in permitting the private ownership of the rights to supply cities with 
 water, electricity, or transportation facilities, extends the field of private 
 gain and correspondingly affects the distribution of wealth. The income 
 received by the successful manager of a municipal waterworks plant is un- 
 doubtedly a very different thing from the income the same individual would 
 receive if he were the owner of a franchise permitting him to conduct the 
 business of supplying the city with water as a private undertaking. The 
 policy of leasing, rather than selling, public lands, which has been adopted 
 by some of the newer American states, is bound to have an appreciable, 
 even if not a very important, effect upon the distribution of wealth. 
 
 In the institution of inheritance we have an instrument which once in a 
 generation redistributes the property rights in existing wealth. It is not 
 strange that those who wish to limit or retard the growth of large individual 
 fortunes have looked to the control and especially to the taxation of inherit- 
 ances as a means to this end. Doubtless the prevalence of large landed 
 estates in England is closely connected with the English law of primogeniture, 
 just as the predominance of small holdings in France is in part due to the 
 French law forbidding the disinheritance of any of one's children. 
 
 Personal freedom, as a legally guaranteed institution, is also of fundamental 
 importance. The factors determining the income of the free workingman 
 are very different from those determining the portion of the slave. It should 
 be remembered, too, that the actual processes by which wealth is distributed 
 are to-day largely controlled by the institution of contract. What rent, wages, 
 or interest one gives or receives is no longer fixed by custom, as in the middle 
 ages, but is a matter of agreement between individuals. So far as Society 
 limits the right of contract, as in the case of legislation regulating the employ- 
 ment of women and children, it correspondingly affects the distribution of 
 wealth. 
 
 These fundamental institutions are discussed more fully elsewhere in this 
 treatise. They are mentioned in this connection in order to emphasize more 
 definitely the fact that the distribution of wealth takes place under the con- 
 ditions imposed by the existing social order. Even the most radical advocates 
 of greater equality in the distribution of wealth do not propose an arbitrary 
 leveling down of fortunes. They direct their attacks against one or more of 
 these fundamental institutions, such as inheritance, private property in land, 
 or private property in production goods. Then there are many persons who 
 are willing to accept the conditions imposed by the existing social order, 
 as a field for the operation of competitive forces in wealth distribution, but 
 who object to monopoly and special privilege. This suggests that the forces 
 bringing about distribution on the basis of the existing social order are in
 
 318 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 themselves amenable to social control. If those who secure the chief prizes 
 in the economic struggle may plume themselves on the fact that they are the 
 victors in a game that is open to all, it is none the less true that society lays 
 down the rules of the game. 
 
 A large part of the complex of institutions and regulations through which 
 society controls distribution work smoothly and silently, their action, so far 
 as society at large is concerned, being unconscious. It is only when obvious 
 conflicts arise between some of the effects of this unconscious control on the 
 one hand and present-day ideals of social welfare on the other hand, that the 
 significance of any part of this fundamental institutional control becomes 
 generally felt. It is not the least of the merits of the study of economics that 
 it emphasizes the fundamental character of that part of the social control 
 of wealth production and wealth distribution which lies below the horizon 
 of social consciousness. 
 
 The Distributive Process. If each family produced all that it 
 consumed, as most families still do in part, there would be no 
 problem of distribution, except whatever problems might arise 
 as to the factors determining the amount produced by each 
 family. But, since most men to-day are working in more or less 
 specialized employments, and for money incomes, the fact is, as 
 was suggested in a previous chapter, that distribution takes place 
 through a process of valuation. Some men (manufacturers, mer- 
 chants, farmers) make a money income by selling goods for more 
 than it costs them to produce them or to buy them from others, 
 while other men (laborers, salaried employees, professional men, 
 capitalists, landowners) get a money income by selling their serv- 
 ices or by selling the use of their capital or land. In the first 
 case, the money income takes the form of profits; in the second 
 case, it is wages, interest, or rent, as the case may be. A man's 
 real income consists of the commodities and services that satisfy 
 his wants; and the extent to which his money income can be 
 transmuted into real income depends on the prices of these things. 
 One always has the option, of course, of investing part of his 
 money income in production goods rather than in consumption 
 goods, thus giving up part of his present real income for a larger 
 future income. However, since different men have to pay about 
 the same prices for the same kinds of goods, a_discussion of the 
 factors determining money incomes will be, ipso facto, a discus- 
 sion of the factors determining real incomes, except as it is found
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 319 
 
 that certain kinds of incomes are changed more readily to meet 
 the conditions imposed by changes in prices than are other kinds 
 of incomes. 
 
 It is obvious that one person may be the recipient of more than 
 one kind of income. The American farmer who owns the land, 
 buildings, farm machinery, and live stock that make up his pro- 
 ductive equipment, and who does part of his own work, is at the 
 same time entrepreneur, landlord, capitalist, and laborer; and 
 his income is made up of different proportions of profits, rent, 
 interest, and wages. The net income of a tenant farmer, utilizing 
 only borrowed capital, and employing only hired labor, would, on 
 the other hand, consist entirely of profits. The economic analysis 
 that seeks to determine the rules governing the apportionment of 
 the annual dividend under the categories of profits, wages, rent, 
 and interest, bears only indirectly upon the question of the per- 
 sonal distribution of wealth. The income that any individual re- 
 ceives depends primarily upon his relative efficiency as a wage 
 earner or as an entrepreneur, or upon the amount and the in- 
 come-yielding capacity of the capital and land which he owns. 
 His ownership of capital and land may have come about through 
 the thrifty husbanding of portions of his income in previous years, 
 or it may have come about through gifts or inheritance. 
 
 Distribution as Valuation. To explain the value which society 
 puts upon personal services is to explain wages; to explain the 
 values attached to the use of land and capital is to explain rent and 
 interest. Certain special and distinguishing characteristics enter 
 into the determination of each of these three kinds of value. The 
 conditions governing the supply of labor are, for example, very 
 different from the conditions governing the supply of land. Yet 
 there are some fundamental facts that are the same for all of these 
 three kinds of valuation. The most important of these common 
 factors is the law of diminishing productivity. 
 
 Assume as an illustration that a certain farm is cultivated by a 
 farmer who uses only his own labor, together with a certain amount 
 of capital in the form of draft animals and agricultural imple- 
 ments. Let us assume further that his land is devoted exclusively 
 to the growing of one crop, corn, for instance. His money
 
 320 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 income will depend on the amount of corn he can produce and the 
 prices he can get for it. If prices remain constant, he can increase 
 his income only by increasing his product. His product may be 
 increased by the use of any one of a number of different methods. 
 In the first place, he can hire a farm laborer to assist him. The 
 two men, working together, will undoubtedly be able to get a 
 larger product from the farm than one man could. In some cases 
 they may be able to get double, or even, through the advantages 
 of cooperation, more than double, what the farmer could produce 
 working alone. More often, perhaps, the employment of the sec- 
 ond man will not double the total product. However that may 
 be, it is absolutely certain that if the farmer employs a third, a 
 fourth, or even more men, he will sooner or later reach a point 
 where it will be found that the employment of the last man has 
 not increased the product as much as it was increased by the 
 last previous laborer. That is, the addition of the third man may 
 not have increased the product as much as the employment of the 
 second man did, or the fourth man may not have increased the 
 product as much as the third man did. This point is called 
 the point of diminishing productivity, 1 for after this point is once 
 reached it will be found that, save under the most exceptional 
 conditions, each successive additional laborer will increase the ag- 
 gregate product by an amount less than the last previous laborer 
 added to it. This fact is not due to any differences in the laborers, 
 whom we assume to be of equal efficiency. It means simply that 
 as the productive possibilities of the farm with its equipment of 
 capital become more fully exploited through more careful tillage, 
 it requires increasingly greater efforts, in the form of still more 
 careful and thorough tillage, to increase the product by a given 
 amount. This is a fact of such common observation that it needs 
 no statistical proof; although various agricultural experiment 
 stations have made records of the effect of different degrees of 
 thoroughness of cultivation upon the yield of different crops. 
 
 1 In some economic writings what is here called "diminishing productivity" 
 is termed "diminishing returns." It seems preferable to reserve the latter term 
 for its more familiar application to the phenomenon of the increasing costs connected 
 with the extension of agricultural cultivation.
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 3 2I 
 
 One might imagine, at first thought, that, after the point of 
 diminishing productivity had been reached, it would not pay the 
 farmer to hire additional laborers. But the only question that 
 directly concerns the farmer in this connection is whether an addi- 
 tional laborer will "earn his wages," that is, whether the added 
 product will sell for enough to cover the additional expense incurred 
 for wages. It will pay the farmer to extend his employment of 
 labor up to the point where the addition of another laborer to the 
 working force would increase the product by an amount too small 
 to sell for enough to pay the wages of the laborer, and where the 
 deduction of a laborer from the working force would decrease 
 the product by an amount at least sufficient to pay the wages of 
 the laborer. If the farmer stops short of this point, he is not mak- 
 ing all the possible profits; if he goes beyond it, he is cutting 
 down his profits by employing labor which does not "earn its 
 wages." The last laborer employed (not necessarily any particu- 
 lar laborer, nor the last in point of time) is the marginal laborer, 
 and the increase in the total product attributable to the marginal 
 laborer (the part which would be lost if one less laborer were em- 
 ployed) is the marginal product of labor. If the farmer has esti- 
 mated product and prices accurately, it will be found, of course, 
 that the value of the marginal product of labor will be approxi- 
 mately equal to the wages of the marginal laborer. Or, since the 
 laborers are supposed to be of equal efficiency, and hence to re- 
 ceive uniform wages, the statement may be put in the broader 
 and more significant form that wages and the marginal product of 
 labor will tend to equal each other. 
 
 The diagrams illustrate the principle of the diminishing productivity of 
 labor, developed in the foregoing analysis. In Figure i the rectangle OM 
 represents the amount of corn that the farmer could raise on his land if work- 
 ing alone, with his given equipment of capital. The rectangle AN represents 
 the increase in the product effected by the addition of another worker. Simi- 
 larly, BP, CQ, DR, and 5 represent respectively the additions to the product 
 resulting from the employment of a third, fourth, fifth, and sixth laborer. 
 If DR bushels of corn the increment in the product attributable to the fifth 
 laborer sells for about enough to pay the wages of one laborer, the 
 farmer will refuse to employ the sixth laborer, while the employment of the 
 fifth would be a matter of indifference. If the fifth laborer were employed, 
 Y
 
 322 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the proceeds of the sale of that part of the total product represented by the 
 rectangle OERH would be used up in the payment of wages (including pay- 
 
 
 
 
 p 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 w 
 
 D 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 / 
 
 \ t 
 
 5 < 
 
 Fic 
 
 : i 
 ;. i 
 
 3 
 
 F 
 
 ment for the farmer's own work, as a laborer), while the part of the product 
 represented by the small rectangles above the line HW would be left to rec- 
 ompense the farmer for the use of his land, for the interest on and wear and 
 tear of his capital. If any surplus is left after these demands are satisfied, it 
 would, of course, constitute the farmer's profits. If the conditions were as 
 
 assumed, the fifth la- 
 borer would be the mar- 
 ginal laborer, and the 
 product represented by 
 the rectangle DR would 
 be the marginal product 
 of labor. 
 
 If we were dealing with 
 a very large undertaking, 
 in which many laborers 
 are employed, the succes- 
 sive rectangles represent- 
 ing the increments in the 
 p IG 2 product attributed to the 
 
 hypothetical addition of 
 
 successive laborers could be conceived as indefinitely narrow, so that the 
 graphic representation would take the form represented in Figure 2, where 
 the line AM is located at the point of diminishing productivity, and 
 where the line BN represents the marginal product of labor. In this 
 case the rectangle OBNH represents the part of the total product which 
 will just suffice to pay the wages of all the laborers employed.
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 3 2 3 
 
 Thus far we have supposed that the farmer is content to get 
 along with his original amount of land and capital, and to increase 
 his product by means of an increased use of labor. Other pos- 
 sibilities are, of course, open to him. It might happen that he 
 would be content to do without additional laborers, using instead 
 an increased equipment of capital. By purchasing more draft 
 animals, more labor-saving machinery, improved fertilizers, or 
 possibly by installing drains or irrigation ditches, as the case may 
 be, he may be able to raise considerably more corn than he could 
 without such investments. But here, again, he will find the possi- 
 bilities of increasing his product subject to the same limitations 
 that would have prevailed had he increased his labor force. With 
 a team of horses he will be able to accomplish more than he could 
 with one horse; two teams of horses may still further increase the 
 productivity of the farm; a third would probably be of very little 
 advantage, and a fourth team still less useful. So with invest- 
 ments of capital in other forms: the law of diminishing produc- 
 tivity is a remorseless physical fact which the farmer has to reckon 
 with. But the concrete form in which the problem presents itself 
 to him is this: Will a further investment of money in a specific 
 kind of capital goods pay me ? Here the farmer has to make on 
 the one hand the best estimate he can of the amount which the 
 proposed capital goods will add to his annual product, and of the 
 probable selling value of the increased product. On the other 
 hand, he has to count his increased annual expenses. These will 
 include (i) the original cost of the additional equipment, divided 
 into annual costs according to its probable durability (each year's 
 costs being properly only the wear and tear, or "depreciation" 
 attributable to that year's use); (2) the maintenance or upkeep 
 (including such things as ordinary repairs on machinery and the 
 cost of feeding horses), and (3) the interest on the investment (what 
 the farmer has to pay if he borrows the necessary funds from 
 some one else, or what he might have lent his money for to 
 some one else if he uses his own funds). Guided by these esti- 
 mates, the farmer will naturally increase his equipment of capital 
 goods so far as the returns from the added product would more 
 than suffice to cover his increased costs. Beyond this point he
 
 324 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 could not wisely go. The last increment of capital which just 
 suffices to pay for itself is the marginal increment of capital, 
 and the added product attributable to it is the marginal product of 
 capital. 
 
 The diagrams portraying the operation of the law of the diminishing prod- 
 uctivity of labor will serve as well to illustrate the diminishing productivity 
 of capital. Assuming that the amount of land and the amount of labor to 
 be utilized are definite in quantity, the successive rectangles in Figure i rep- 
 resent the increase in the gross product attributable to each of successive 
 increments of capital. Figure 2 represents the same conditions, except that 
 each increment of capital is assumed to be indefinitely small. 
 
 If (in Figure 2) BN represents the marginal product of capital, the whole 
 return imputed to capital is, of course, represented by the rectangle OBNH. 
 The area above the line H N represents the part of the product which is avail- 
 able for rent and wages, the farmer's profits being derived from any surplus 
 that is left after these demands are satisfied. 
 
 There is one difficulty in the foregoing analysis, however, that may have 
 been noted by the reader. What is meant by an "increment of capital"? 
 In the case of labor the "increment of labor" can be interpreted as the labor 
 of one man (for any definite period of time that may be chosen), the one man 
 being assumed (for the purpose of simplicity in the analysis) to be of equal 
 efficiency with all others constituting the labor supply. It is just as practicable, 
 of course, to assume that one horse is, for the farmer's purposes, just as 
 efficient as another horse, that only one kind of plow is available, and that 
 one bushel of fertilizer is exactly like any other bushel of fertilizer ; but this 
 does not help us out of our difficulty. For how can we blend horses, plows, 
 and fertilizers into one concept, and divide them into " increments of capital " ? 
 One way of getting around the difficulty is to think of the capital which the 
 farmer combines with his labor and his land in terms of its money value. In 
 this sense an increment of capital might be a dollar's worth of capital, or ten 
 dollars' worth of capital, without reference to the different kinds of concrete 
 production goods really composing it. This device is useful for some purposes, 
 but it obscures the fundamental fact that capital gets its value from its ability 
 to secure an income for its owner. The purpose of this analysis of diminish- 
 ing productivity is to open the way for a discussion of the valuation of the 
 services of land, labor, and capital. To use the term " capital " in the sense 
 of capital value at this stage in the discussion would only lead us into a circular 
 argument. This point cannot be further elaborated here, but should be 
 kept in mind by the reader in connection with the discussion of interest in a 
 subsequent chapter. 1 As a matter of fact the law of diminishing productivity 
 
 1 Professor J. B. Clark avoids the difficulty here discussed by using the term 
 "capital" in a sense which corresponds neither to the concrete instruments of pro- 
 duction that make up capital goods, nor to the value of these capital goods,
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 325 
 
 holds for each specific kind of capital that the farmer uses. For example, 
 imagine that the farmer is limited to the use of a fixed amount of all forms of 
 capital except one, horses, for instance. Then the successive rectangles in 
 Figure i would represent very well the increments of product gained by the 
 use of additional horses, while if the product added by the use of a fifth 
 horse is just about enough to pay for the increased expense, the rectangle DR 
 would represent the marginal product. The illustration can, by a similar 
 process, be made to apply to any other kind of capital. The farmer will 
 normally make use of each specific kind of capital up to the marginal point. 
 
 A third way of increasing his product is also open to the farmer. 
 He may think it wiser to get along with his original equipment of 
 capital and his own labor, and to increase his product by utilizing 
 more land. The adoption of this procedure would mean a less 
 intensive cultivation per acre of land. The use of labor and capital 
 would have to be distributed more thinly over the larger acreage. 
 This would result in a smaller product per acre, but the procedure 
 would be warranted if the increase in the annual product should 
 sell for more than the annual cost of the additional acreage. By 
 the annual cost of additional land we mean the rent which the 
 farmer has to pay for the land if he leases it, or the interest on the 
 amount of the purchase price, if he buys it. It is obvious, how- 
 ever, that the combination of more and more land with a fixed 
 amount of labor and capital will result in a smaller and smaller 
 return per acre of land, and that a point will soon be reached be- 
 yond which it will not pay the farmer to go. In other words, the 
 law of diminishing productivity rules when land is considered as 
 the variable factor, just as it does when labor or capital is consid- 
 ered as the variable. 
 
 The diagrams already used may be adapted to the illustration of the present 
 hypothesis by assuming that equal areas, if successively combined with a 
 given amount of labor and capital, would yield increments of product as 
 represented by the successive rectangles in Figure i, or by the curve in Fig- 
 ure 2. It is assumed for the sake of simplicity in the illustration that the dif- 
 ferent acres of land available for the farmer's use are of equal fertility. 
 
 but as denoting a self- perpetuating fund which bears the same relation to concrete 
 production goods (including land) that a river does to the drops of water of which it, 
 at a given time, is composed. Professor Clark finds this concept useful in his 
 own analysis (cf. his Distribution of Wealth and Essentials of Economic Theory), 
 but it is altogether too abstract and hypothetical to be of use in the present con- 
 nection.
 
 326 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The Actual Operation of Diminishing Productivity. It has 
 been assumed thus far that the farmer of our illustration has to 
 be content with a fixed quantity of two of the three factors in 
 production, but that he is at liberty to increase his use of the third 
 factor up to the point where the maximum profits will be gained 
 for himself. Assuming in turn that each of the three factors in 
 production was the variable one, we found that in each case the 
 law was the same maximum profits were obtained when the 
 product added by the last increment of the variable factor would 
 sell for just enough l to cover the increased expense. In one way, 
 however, this assumption does not correspond with the facts. 
 The farmer is at liberty to increase his products by increasing his 
 utilization, not only of any one, but of any two, or all of the three, 
 factors of production. He may, for example, purchase more draft 
 animals and more machinery, employ more labor, and at the same 
 time acquire more land. To a certain extent the use of one factor 
 may lessen the use of another (as in the case of labor-saving ma- 
 chinery and labor). More often, however, the reverse is true. 
 The acquisition of machinery may necessitate the use of more 
 horses, while the acquisition of more land will often make profit- 
 able the use of more labor as well as more capital a fact 
 which is itself implied in the law of diminishing productivity. 
 Although the employment of labor, capital, and land can thus be 
 increased simultaneously, the significance of the law of diminish- 
 ing productivity is in no wise diminished. The farmer, in decid- 
 ing upon the purchase of a particular kind of capital good, has to 
 take into account his present and, to some extent, even his prob- 
 able future supply of other kinds of capital goods, as well as of 
 land and labor, before he can form a judgment as to the amount 
 which the use of the particular capital good will add to his annual 
 product. Moreover, he has to choose between additional invest- 
 ments in labor as against additional investments in land, or ad- 
 ditional investments in different kinds of capital. But his effort 
 to get maximum profits will lead him to make those investments 
 
 1 Whether this last unit, which just pays for itself, will be added, is, of course, 
 a matter of indifference. The margin is consequently sometimes called the 
 "margin of indifference."
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 327 
 
 which promise to result in the greatest additions to his product. 
 The result of this will be, normally, that each factor in production 
 will be utilized up to the marginal point the point where further 
 utilization would add a product so small as to sell for less than 
 the increased expenses. 
 
 Why the farmer should not increase his product indefinitely by increasing 
 his use of all three of the factors in production is a question which does not 
 concern us in this connection. The law of diminishing productivity relates 
 only to the proportions in which land, labor, and different forms of capital 
 are combined. The question of the most profitable size of farm is quite 
 another thing. 1 
 
 It is not only in agriculture that the law of diminishing produc- 
 tivity is the fundamental thing in determining the proportions in 
 which the factors of production are combined. Every manufac- 
 turer has the option of using either relatively more machinery and 
 relatively less labor, or relatively less machinery and relatively 
 more labor in order to produce a certain quantity of goods. He 
 may have to decide, also, between building a six-story factory 
 covering an acre of ground, and a one-story factory covering six 
 acres of ground a problem which is paralleled by the farmer's 
 problem of deciding between the cultivation of a relatively large 
 acreage and the more intensive cultivation of a smaller acreage. 
 The entrepreneur in every kind of undertaking has to decide as 
 to the advisability of a particular investment in land, capital, or 
 labor, with reference to the fundamental question, "Will it 
 pay?" And the profitableness of any such investment is always 
 a matter of the cost of the unit of land, labor, or capital, as com- 
 pared with the selling value of the quantity which it will add to 
 the entrepreneur's total product. 
 
 1 The limitations to the profitable size of a farm or other business unit arise 
 from the fact that the managerial efficiency of the entrepreneur is itself subject 
 to the law of diminishing productivity. Under competition there is a constant 
 tendency for labor, capital, and land to get into the hands of those entrepreneurs 
 who can use them most efficiently, that is, who can pay most for them because they 
 can get the largest product from them. But even if A is a better entrepreneur than 
 B, it may easily happen that B can get a larger product from additional units of 
 labor, capital, and land than A can, if B's existing equipment is considerably 
 smaller than A's. A given farmer cannot extend his use of land, labor, and capital 
 indefinitely, simply because, after his establishment reaches a certain size, other
 
 328 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 In order to achieve maximum profits, each entrepreneur will en- 
 deavor, so far as is practicable, to apportion his use of land, labor, 
 and capital so that the value of the increment of product attributable 
 to the marginal unit of each factor in production will about equal 
 its expense. 
 
 The significance of the law of diminishing productivity in rela- 
 tion to the distribution of wealth now becomes apparent. If a 
 given class of laborers in a given employment receive like wages, 
 their wages (being the same as the wages of the marginal laborer) 
 will tend to equal the marginal product of labor. The expense 
 incurred by the entrepreneur for any unit of a certain kind of capi- 
 tal goods will tend to equal the value of the marginal product of 
 that particular kind of capital goods. The rent which the farmer 
 will pay for any acre of a quantity of land of uniform quality will 
 tend to equal the value of the marginal product of land of that 
 quality. But so far as competition works freely, different entre- 
 preneurs in the same market will have to pay the same wages for 
 the same kind of labor, the same price for the same kind of capi- 
 tal goods, and the same rent for the same kind of land; and they 
 will get the same prices for the same kinds of products. So it is 
 possible to state in more general terms that the remuneration of 
 each factor in production tends to equal its marginal product. 1 
 
 farmers can use additional units of the productive factors more profitably than he 
 can. The most profitable size of the business unit will vary, other things being 
 equal, with the efficiency of the entrepreneur. 
 
 Some writers have introduced the efficiency of the entrepreneur as a fourth 
 variable in their discussion of diminishing productivity. Such a procedure is 
 avoided in this book, because it leads to theoretical complexities and because it 
 involves a shifting of the point of view. The diminishing productivity of each of 
 the three factors in production is a physical fact which every entrepreneur has to 
 deal with, and which we can explain most clearly by adhering to the analysis of 
 the motives controlling the individual entrepreneur. The analysis of the dimin- 
 ishing productivity of the entrepreneur's efficiency, on the other hand, involves of 
 necessity the social point of view, for the only kind of estimate that is made of the 
 entrepreneur's productivity is expressed through the social process of the valuation 
 of the entrepreneur's products. In this book the diminishing productivity analysis 
 is applied only to the entrepreneur's expenses of production, the entrepreneur 
 being regarded (as he is in accounting practice) as the "residual claimant." 
 
 1 The statement that rewards tend to equal products has no ethical significance, 
 and should not be interpreted as a justification of the present economic order, 
 and this for the following reasons among others: (i) That distribution ought to
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 3 2 9 
 
 It is not necessary for the validity of this marginal productivity 
 theory of distribution, as it is called, that in any particular under- 
 taking at any given time the proportions in which the factors of 
 production are actually combined should be adjusted with the 
 nicety which the theory seems to imply. The amount of land which 
 the farmer holds at any one time is apt to be fixed by his estimate 
 of his future rather than of his present production, while custom, 
 pride of ownership, and the chance of gain through an increase 
 in land values (which is not to be confused with the motives guid- 
 ing his activity as a producer) have their influence. Moreover, 
 the size of the government homesteads into which a large part of 
 
 be according to productivity is itself a debatable proposition. Some socialists, 
 for example, maintain that distribution according to needs is a higher ideal. 
 (2) The ethical side of the problem of distribution relates to personal distribution, 
 while the marginal productivity doctrine relates to the determination of the in- 
 comes going to the different factors in production. To state that the rent of an 
 acre of land tends to equal the value of its product is not to say that the landowner 
 has "earned " his income. The private receipt of rent depends upon such social 
 institutions as private property, inheritance, and free contract, and these have to 
 be judged from the broad viewpoint of social welfare. (3) The efficiency of the 
 individual laborer, which is one of the things determining his productivity, often 
 depends upon the opportunity he has had to "make the most of himself." But 
 opportunity depends largely on environment, and this in turn is to a large extent 
 amenable to social control. (4) The amount of the marginal product of any one 
 factor in production is itself a resultant of all the forces affecting the supply of all 
 the factors in production and of all the conditions that affect their fitness to serve 
 in the production of the things that consumers are demanding. (5) This theory 
 is only a statement of a normal tendency. It does not, properly understood! 
 conflict with the fact that such things as custom and other forms of economic 
 friction and inertia, the higgling of the market, the conscious efforts of social classes 
 to better their condition, imperfections in the monetary system, short-sighted 
 selfishness on the one hand, altruism on the other, as well as the conscious social 
 control expressed in labor legislation, usury laws, and the like, all have important 
 effects upon the incomes actually received by those who furnish labor, capital, and 
 land for the work of production. Actual wages may differ from the normal wages 
 measured by marginal product just as contractual rent may differ from economic 
 rent. (6) We can imagine an economic order very different from the present one in 
 which it would still be true that incomes would tend to equal products. If, for 
 example, wages were arbitrarily increased 50 per cent by law, while one result 
 would undoubtedly be an increase in unemployment, it would still be true that 
 wages would tend to equal the marginal product of labor, or, rather, that the 
 marginal product of labor would tend to equal wages. To attempt to avoid this 
 difficulty by assuming that the present order, or a purely competitive order, is the 
 " natural " order of things, is to beg the whole question in favor of the existing 
 status.
 
 330 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the public domain was divided has had an important effect on 
 the size of the farmer's holding in a large section of the United 
 States. The average American farmer undoubtedly holds more 
 land than he would if he were looking only for maximum present 
 profits. The practical problem for him is apt to be how inten- 
 sively he shall cultivate it: how much labor and capital he shall 
 combine with it. That is, he is apt to use relatively more land 
 and relatively less labor and capital than he would use if every 
 additional acre of land used meant an additional expense for 
 land. This conclusion is not altered by the fact that his land is 
 probably not of uniform quality, and that some of it may not repay 
 cultivation under present conditions. In a similar way the manu- 
 facturer builds his factory for the future, and may even equip it 
 with a larger complement of some kinds of machines (such as 
 boilers and engines) than present requirements justify. On the 
 other hand, a sudden and probably temporary increase in demand 
 for a product will be met by the manufacturers by the employ- 
 ment of more labor (even at the high rate charged for overtime or 
 night work) rather than by the installation of more labor-saving 
 machinery, even though the latter might, in the long run, be more 
 economical. In general, when considerations which take into 
 account a period of years dominate, land and the more perma- 
 nent forms of capital goods will be used more freely, labor and 
 the less permanent forms of capital goods less freely. When 
 short-time considerations are dominant, the reverse will be 
 true. 
 
 These limitations do not invalidate the law of the equality of 
 the remuneration of the factors in production and the value of 
 their marginal products any more than the fact that a feather 
 does not fall through the atmosphere as rapidly as a stone invali- 
 dates the law of gravitation. This law, like other economic laws, 
 is the statement of a fundamental tendency, which, in this case, is 
 bound up with the universal desire of entrepreneurs to get for 
 themselves the largest possible profits. 
 
 Marginal Productivity and Valuation. The reader who has 
 firmly grasped the concept of marginal utility will find that a 
 recognition of some similarities in the roles which marginal utility
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 
 
 331 
 
 and marginal productivity play in the process of valuation will 
 help him to grasp the significance of the latter concept. The value 
 of consumption goods is determined by their capacity to yield an 
 income of satisfactions; the value of production goods is deter- 
 mined by their capacity to yield a money income to the entre- 
 preneur. In the one case the law of diminishing utility is domi- 
 nant; in the other case, the law of diminishing productivity. Just 
 as we cannot speak of the utility of a commodity in general, but 
 only of the utility of particular units of a commodity, so we can- 
 not speak of the productivity of land, labor, or capital in general, 
 but only of the productivity of particular units of land, labor, and 
 capital a productivity which is attributed or imputed to other 
 similar units of the supply of these factors in production. The 
 consumer is getting the maximum of satisfaction of his wants when 
 the final dollar spent for one commodity satisfies just as intense 
 wants as the final dollar spent for any other commodity, and he 
 tends to apportion his expenditures accordingly. The entrepreneur 
 is not making maximum profits if his final expenditures for any 
 one of the factors in production add more to his product than his 
 final expenditure (of equal amount) for either of the other factors 
 in production, and he tends to apportion his employment of land, 
 labor, and capital accordingly. But it must not be supposed that 
 the statement that the prices paid for land, labor, and capital tend 
 to equal the value of their marginal products is a complete explana- 
 tion of the valuation of the services of the factors in production 
 any more than the principle of marginal utility is a complete ex- 
 planation of the valuation of consumption goods. In fact, from 
 one point of view, marginal productivity is itself partly deter- 
 mined by the prices which the entrepreneur has to pay for the 
 services of the factors in production. 
 
 The demand for the use of land, labor, and capital is ultimately 
 a demand for their products the goods that satisfy human wants. 
 The entrepreneur's task is to anticipate and meet this demand 
 a problem that takes the concrete form of producing goods that 
 will sell for more than the expense of production. On the one 
 hand he has to estimate the quantities which he can sell at certain 
 prices; on the other hand, he has to take account of the quantities
 
 332 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 which various units of land, labor, and capital will contribute to 
 his product, together with the prices (wages, rent, and interest) 
 that he has to pay for these units. Through his mediation the 
 demand of society for want-satisfying goods becomes a demand 
 for the services of certain quantities of land, labor, and capital, 
 combined in certain proportions. And the principle that guides 
 the entrepreneur's transformation of the social demand for the 
 products of land, labor, and capital into his own demand for the 
 services of these factors in production is the principle of marginal 
 productivity. The wages, rent, and interest that are actually paid 
 for the services of the factors in production are the resultants of 
 the, demand of entrepreneurs, on the one hand, and of the supply 
 of these factors on the other hand. The principle of marginal 
 productivity is an illuminating way of stating the problem of the 
 distribution of wealth, rather than a solution of it. Just how supply 
 and demand operate in the case of each factor in production is a 
 topic to be considered in later chapters. 
 
 Social Aspects of Diminishing Productivity. Since the entre- 
 preneurs are only the intermediaries between society viewed as a 
 body of consumers and society viewed as a body of producers, we 
 may, for present purposes, leave them out of consideration, in 
 order to fix our attention upon some of the more general results 
 of the fact of diminishing productivity. 
 
 If the number of laborers within the boundaries of a nation is 
 increased by immigration, without a corresponding increase in 
 capital or in the amount of land available for use, the result will be 
 an increase in the total amount of goods produced, which means 
 an increase in the amount of wealth produced per unit c* land and 
 capital, but (on account of the operation of the law of diminishing 
 productivity) a decreased amount per laborer; a higher marginal 
 product for land and capital, and a lower marginal product for 
 labor; consequently, higher rent and higher interest, but lower 
 wages. If the supply of capital within a country is increased, 
 while labor and land remain constant, the result will be higher 
 wages and higher rents, but a smaller remuneration for capital. 
 Similarly, if the available supply of land be increased (as by im- 
 provements in transportation facilities), rent will absorb relatively
 
 DISTRIBUTION AS AN ECONOMIC PROBLEM 333 
 
 less, and wages and interest relatively more, of the value of the 
 total product. 
 
 In a very real sense the same laborer is more productive in a 
 country where land is relatively plentiful than in a country where 
 land is relatively scarce. A laborer may gain no technical effi- 
 ciency by migration from Europe to America, but the increment 
 of product attributable to his work is apt to be considerably larger 
 in the United States than it was in Europe. Here he really creates 
 a larger product and earns a larger wage. The migrations of 
 labor and capital from one region to another, or from one country 
 to another, are guided by the endeavors of capitalists and laborers 
 to get the maximum remuneration, which will always be found 
 where the value of the marginal product of capital or labor is a 
 maximum. 
 
 In a prosperous country it is apt to be the case that the supply 
 of labor and the supply of capital are being increased simultane- 
 ously, though not necessarily with equal rapidity, while more land 
 is at the same time being made available through improvements 
 in transportation. Save under such exceptional conditions of rail- 
 way building as have prevailed in the United States during the 
 past fifty years, the available supply of land is apt to increase 
 more slowly than the other factors in production increase. In 
 general, the law of diminishing productivity will necessitate a con- 
 tinual increase in the proportion of the product set aside for the 
 remuneration of each unit of the most slowly increasing factor in 
 production; while, of the other two factors, the one that increases 
 more rapidly will receive, per unit, a relatively smaller and smaller 
 proportion of the value of the total product. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Do you know of any instances where the distribution of wealth has been 
 affected, directly or indirectly, by conscious social action ? 
 
 2. Prepare tables or diagrams illustrating the operation of the law of 
 diminishing productivity in some industry with which you are familiar. 
 
 3. Why is the same laborer more productive in America than in Europe ? 
 Is this a condition that will probably continue indefinitely? 
 
 4. Why do lands in Belgium produce more per acre than similar lands in 
 the United States?
 
 334 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 5. Why are twenty-story office buildings not erected in small cities ? 
 
 6. What is the relation of the discussion in this chapter to the socialist 
 contention that labor produces all wealth? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. II. 
 COMMONS, J. R. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. III. 
 FETTER, F. A. The Principles of Economics, Chap. IX. 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, Vol. I, 4th ed., Book VI, 
 Chaps. I and II.
 
 CHAPTER XX 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 IN the present chapter we shall study the distribution of wealth 
 and income among individuals simply as individuals, and not as 
 factors of production. What is the cause of large fortunes? Is 
 the middle class disappearing? Can we abolish poverty? In 
 the chapter on Consumption, reference has been made to the ideal 
 distribution of wealth, here we shall deal chiefly with actual 
 conditions. But to begin with, certain distinctions must be clearly 
 drawn. 
 
 Wealth and Income. The distribution of wealth and income 
 should be distinguished. If we have in mind simply the enjoy- 
 ment of material things, then we must pay attention to the distri- 
 bution of income. A man of vast possessions may be very frugal 
 in his consumption, acting with respect to most of his property 
 simply as a trustee for society. But when we are interested in 
 social classes, industrial democracy, and personal power and inde- 
 pendence, then the distribution of wealth is the important con- 
 sideration. 
 
 Absolute and Relative Well-being. Two entirely independent 
 inquiries are very frequently confused, (i) We may wish to 
 know whether the condition of the mass of the people is getting 
 better or worse. Do they have more or less of the good things of 
 life than their ancestors had? But we may also ask, (2) What 
 share of the total product of industry is received by each section 
 of the community? Which section is gaining upon the others? 
 If A and B divide a catch of ten fish equally to-day, and if to- 
 morrow A gets ten out of a total catch of thirty, then absolutely 
 his income has increased, but relatively it has declined. 
 
 Concentration of Wealth and Large-scale Production. It is per- 
 haps worth while to warn the reader against confusing the question 
 
 335
 
 336 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of large and small fortunes with the question of large and small 
 scale production. However improbable, it is at least conceivable 
 that there might be an equality of property with production 
 carried on largely as it is to-day, for we have but to imagine an 
 equal distribution of stock holdings. 
 
 Methods of measuring Concentration of Wealth and Income. 
 How shall we tell whether the middle class is tending to disappear ? 
 A common method is to make a classification of wealth and income, 
 and then to compare the number of persons in each class at dif- 
 ferent dates. The unreliability of the conclusions based on such a 
 procedure is made clear by the following hypothetical illustra- 
 tion: Let $100 be distributed among ten persons as follows: 
 $i, $3, $5, $7, $9, $11, $13, $15, $17, $19. Then suppose each 
 individual's holding is doubled, thus: $2, $6, $10, $14, $18, 
 $22, $26, $30, $34, $38. Relatively to each other they r are 
 all in the same position as before, but by the erroneous method 
 of comparison referred to, there appears to have been a concen- 
 tration because the number in the highest class has increased most 
 rapidly: 
 
 TABLE I 
 
 CLASS 
 
 NUMBER 
 
 Dollars 
 
 First Case 
 
 Second Case 
 
 o and less than 5 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 2 
 
 6 
 
 5 and less than 10 
 
 ro and less than 15 
 
 15 and over . . .... 
 
 
 A satisfactory method of comparing the distribution of wealth at 
 different epochs must take account of the changing significance of 
 fixed classifications when there has been a change in the per capita 
 wealth. This can be done by observing what proportion of the 
 wealth is owned by certain sections of the population, such as the 
 poorest third, the middle third, or the upper third. If a larger 
 proportion of the total wealth falls into the hands of the upper 
 third, we may say there is evidence of a growing concentration of
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 337 
 
 wealth. It is clear that no definite movement is necessarily dis- 
 cernible even when changes are taking place, for these changes 
 may tend toward concentration in one part of society and toward 
 diffusion in another. 
 
 Statistics of Distribution. There are many investigations 
 showing the earnings of particular classes of workers, but in the 
 United States there is no reliable statement of the division of the 
 national wealth or income among all classes of society. We could 
 not use the property tax assessments for this purpose because of 
 their inaccuracy, and because of the fact that one individual may 
 be taxed in various jurisdictions. The returns of the probate 
 courts have been used as a basis for a statement of wealth distri- 
 bution in the United States on the assumption that the distribution 
 of wealth among persons who die in any year is an index of the 
 distribution of wealth among those who are living. But the in- 
 completeness of our probate returns make this method also a 
 hazardous one. Such statistics as we have do not enable us to 
 say more than that a small proportion of the population at the top 
 of the social scale controls a large proportion of the nation's wealth, 
 but no marked tendency either toward concentration or diffusion 
 in the last fifty years has been proved. 
 
 The growth of the number of millionaires has been used as an 
 evidence of growing wealth concentration, but it should be noted 
 that a growth of population and wealth in a community would 
 cause an increase in the number of millionaires, even if the relation 
 between the various classes remained the same. Suppose that in 
 1850 there had been in the United States but fifty millionaires, that 
 three hundred and fifty persons had from $750,000 to $1,000,000, 
 and that six hundred persons had from $500,000 to $750,000. If 
 the population had remained the same and every one's wealth had 
 been doubled, in 1900 there would have been one thousand mil- 
 lionaires, and if the population at the same time increased fourfold, 
 with the relations among the new population the same as in the old, 
 we should then have four thousand millionaires without any tend- 
 ency toward concentration. Nevertheless, the increase of large 
 fortunes has been so startling that in spite of these considerations 
 one may perhaps regard them as an indication of a growing con-
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 centration of wealth. The lists of very rich men published in the 
 United States from time to time are instructive on this point. In 
 1820 men with a personal property of $20,000 were included; in 
 1846 a total property of $50,000 was considered very large; in 
 1855 this was doubled; in 1892 a man must be a millionaire to be 
 considered very rich, and at present one may speak of even a 
 billionaire. 
 
 More satisfactory statements can be made for those countries 
 which collect an income tax. The following figures are from a 
 table prepared by Professor Wagner, in a study of the income-tax 
 returns of Prussia : 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 INCOMES IN PRUSSIA, 1892 AND 1902 * 
 
 CLASSES IN DOLLARS 
 
 PE CENT OF PERSONS 
 (Heads of Families or Single 
 Adults) 
 
 PER CENT OF INCOME 
 (That below $214 is estimated) 
 
 Below 214 
 
 214. 714. . . 
 
 1892 
 
 1902 
 
 1892 
 
 1902 
 
 78.18 
 18.98 
 
 2-33 
 0.41 
 0.08 
 
 O.OI 
 
 70.66 
 
 2.88 
 0.51 
 
 O.IO 
 O.O2 
 
 41.21 
 
 30.01 
 12.8 
 
 7-37 
 4-65 
 
 3-93 
 
 32-97 
 34-92 
 
 !3-73 
 
 7.84 
 
 5-4 
 
 714-2261 
 2261-7259. .. . 
 7259-23800. .. 
 Over 23800 . . . 
 
 Absolute amounts 
 (Total) 
 
 Number 
 11,162,000 
 
 Number 
 12,813,000 
 
 Dollars 
 2,309,076,000 
 
 Dollars 
 3,039,498,000 
 
 1 From Zeitschrift des Preussischen Statistischen Bureaus, 1904, p. 231. 
 
 The great mass of the people are too poor to pay any income tax 
 at all, the minimum income taxed being $214. The upper 3.51 
 per cent of the population receives about one third the total 
 income, but in connection with such a statement it should be said 
 that even if incomes should be equally distributed, the average 
 income per family, or single adults, would be very small ($237 in 
 1902). With a very moderate inequality in distribution, the mass 
 of the people must still be unable to pay an income tax. Thus, 
 the table shows as much the niggardliness of nature as the injustice
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 339 
 
 of man to man. From 1892 to 1902 there seems to have been an 
 absolute increase in money incomes among the lowest class of the 
 people, since a considerably smaller proportion of the population 
 is found in the class with incomes below $214 in 1902 than in 1892. 
 But the table as a whole shows a slight tendency toward a concen- 
 tration of incomes in the hands of the upper classes. 
 
 When we turn from the question of relative well-being to that of 
 the actual condition of each class taken by itself, we find two facts 
 standing put prominently: (i) the fruits of economic progress 
 have not been confined to a small class, but have been shared by 
 the masses, and (2) a surprisingly large section of the population 
 is still in poverty. 
 
 With respect to the first, we may say that in material comforts 
 the people of this generation are better off than they have ever been 
 before. The work of settlement in which so many of our fore- 
 fathers engaged was laborious and exhausting. Food was often 
 scarce, disease was rife in many settlements, and the women and 
 children in particular suffered greatly. After the wilderness was 
 cleared, there ensued a period of "rude plenty." Food was 
 abundant, but it was coarse in quality and restricted in variety, 
 whilst everything that had to be brought from a distance was very 
 expensive. Education was difficult to secure, books scarce, and 
 the lives of most people were, in the main, monotonous and 
 uneventful. 
 
 The course of wages from the middle of the eighteenth century 
 to the year 1905, and the movement of prices from 1860 to the 
 latter date, are given in Table III following. The figures are not 
 altogether comparable, nor so trustworthy as could be wished, but 
 the general impression which they give is correct. Speaking 
 generally, money wages have steadily risen, and the hours of labor 
 have declined, with minor interruptions, since the colonial period, 
 while prices have fluctuated irregularly. Taking all kinds of com- 
 modities into account, the level of prices in the last half century 
 has probably been little if any above the level of prices in the first 
 half of the nineteenth century. The standard of living has per- 
 ceptibly risen, and the working classes save no more, possibly, 
 than they did several generations ago. But they live better.
 
 340 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 TABLE III 
 
 WAGES, PRICES, AND HOURS OF LABOR 
 
 WAGES, PRICES, AND HOURS 
 
 IN i860 TAKEN AS IOO 
 
 OF LABOR IN 1890 TAKEN 
 
 
 AS IOO 
 
 DAY LABORERS IN 
 MASSACHUSETTS ' 
 
 EMPLOYEES IN MANUFACTURING 
 INDUSTRIES EASTERN STATES 
 
 GENERAL INDUSTRY, EXCLUDING 
 AGRICULTURE, MINING, AND 
 TRANSPORTATION 
 
 
 T? ITT 1 
 
 
 RELATIVE 
 
 
 RELATIVE 
 
 PERIOD 
 
 Ix ILLA- 
 TIVE 
 
 YEAR 
 
 
 Cost 
 
 Hours 
 
 YEAR 
 
 
 
 Hours 
 
 
 WAGES 
 
 
 Wages 
 
 of 
 
 of 
 
 
 Wages < 
 
 Prices s 
 
 of 
 
 
 
 
 
 Living ' 
 
 Labor' 
 
 
 
 
 Labor 6 
 
 1752-60 
 
 29 
 
 1860 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 1881 
 
 95-3 
 
 "4-5 
 
 I3 
 
 1761-70 
 
 325 
 
 1861 
 
 IOO 
 
 III 
 
 99.1 
 
 1882 
 
 96.9 
 
 II7-5 
 
 103 
 
 1771-80 
 
 376 
 
 1862 
 
 IOO 
 
 123 
 
 98.2 
 
 1883 
 
 97-7 
 
 114.8 
 
 I0 3 
 
 1781-90 
 
 .428 
 
 1863 
 
 109 
 
 137 
 
 98.2 
 
 1884 
 
 98-5 
 
 107.7 
 
 I3 
 
 1791-00 
 
 .623 
 
 1864 
 
 1 20 
 
 I6 3 
 
 98.2 
 
 1885 
 
 97-8 
 
 100.8 
 
 103 
 
 1801-10 
 
 .817 
 
 1865 
 
 141 
 
 175 
 
 97-3 
 
 1886 
 
 97.8 
 
 99.6 
 
 IO2 
 
 1811-20 
 
 .910 
 
 1866 
 
 J 53 
 
 172 
 
 98.2 
 
 1887 
 
 98.6 
 
 100.3 
 
 IOO 
 
 1821-30 
 
 .796 
 
 1867 
 
 172 
 
 164 
 
 98.2 
 
 1888 
 
 99- 2 
 
 102. 1 
 
 IOO 
 
 1831-40 
 
 .872 
 
 1868 
 
 167 
 
 I6 5 
 
 96.4 
 
 1889 
 
 99.6 
 
 IO2.I 
 
 IOO 
 
 1841-50 
 
 .852 
 
 1869 
 
 174 
 
 I6 3 
 
 96.4 
 
 1890 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO 
 
 1851-60 
 
 975 
 
 1870 
 
 J 75 
 
 157 
 
 95-5 
 
 1891 
 
 99-7 
 
 101.4 
 
 99-8 
 
 
 
 1871 
 
 178 
 
 148 
 
 95-5 
 
 1892 
 
 100.3 
 
 99-5 
 
 99.8 
 
 
 
 1872 
 
 i74 
 
 147 
 
 95-5 
 
 1893 
 
 IOO. 2 
 
 IO2.O 
 
 99.6 
 
 
 
 1873 
 
 i?S 
 
 149 
 
 95-5 
 
 1894 
 
 96.7 
 
 97-4 
 
 99.1 
 
 
 
 1874 
 
 170 
 
 145 
 
 95-5 
 
 1895 
 
 97-4 
 
 95-5 
 
 99-4 
 
 
 
 1875 
 
 161 
 
 141 
 
 93- 6 
 
 1896 
 
 98-5 
 
 93-3 
 
 99.1 
 
 
 
 1876 
 
 156 
 
 J 34 
 
 93- 6 
 
 1897 
 
 98.2 
 
 94.0 
 
 98.9 
 
 
 
 1877 
 
 146 
 
 I3 1 
 
 93-6 
 
 1898 
 
 99.0 
 
 96.4 
 
 99 -o 
 
 
 
 1878 
 
 142 
 
 126 
 
 93- 6 
 
 1899 
 
 IOO. 2 
 
 97-2 
 
 98-5 
 
 
 
 1879 
 
 140 
 
 123 
 
 93-6 
 
 1900 
 
 I03.I 
 
 98.7 
 
 98.0 
 
 
 
 1880 
 
 137 
 
 125 
 
 93-6 
 
 1901 
 
 104.8 
 
 102.7 
 
 97-4 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1902 
 
 108.2 
 
 108.3 
 
 96.6 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 J 93 
 
 III. 2 
 
 107.7 
 
 95-9 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1904 
 
 III. I 
 
 109.1 
 
 95- 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 *9S 
 
 II2.8 
 
 109.8 
 
 95-2 
 
 1 Data from Report of Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor for 1885, p. 455. 
 
 1 Data from Mitchell, Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard, pp. 242-244. 
 The cost of living here is based upon retail prices and covers rent as well as food, etc. 
 
 3 Based upon statistics covering 21 industries given in the Aldrich Report on Wholesale 
 Prices, Wages, and Transportation. 
 
 * Statistics for 1881-1889 cover 25 city occupations, and are based upon data given in Bul- 
 letin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 18, p. 669. Statistics for 1800-1905 cover 349 occupations, 
 and are based upon data given in Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 65, p. 20. 
 
 'Wholesale prices from 1881 to 1889, based upon data given in the Aldrich Report on 
 Wholesale Wages, Prices, and Transportation, Part I, p. 99. Retail prices of food from 1890 
 to 1005, from the Bulletin last cited. 
 
 6 From the Aldrich Report and Bulletin cited above. After 1890, statistics are based on 
 hours of labor per week.
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 341 
 
 Regarding the second proposition, we may say that reliable 
 English investigations show that more than one fourth of the popu- 
 lation of the cities of London and York are below the poverty line. 
 To be sure, it is not easy to determine definitely how poor a person 
 must be in order to be "in poverty," but the statement just made 
 is based upon standards that are undeniably conservative. But 
 a number of those actually in poverty have enough income to pur- 
 chase the minimum physical requirements if they knew how to 
 spend their money wisely. In the city of York 9.91 per cent of 
 the population had insufficient earnings for minimum require- 
 ments estimated at $5.25 per week for a family of five. This 
 minimum is very low, and it is easily within the mark to say that 
 at least a fifth of the population of York did not have in 1899 a 
 sufficient income for a decent existence. In the United States 
 the proportion of the urban population below the poverty line is 
 probably somewhat less, but reliable statistics cannot be quoted. 
 
 A recent writer has estimated that ten million persons in the 
 United States are in poverty, not all in distress, but "much of the 
 time underfed, poorly clothed, and improperly housed." The 
 estimate is based on statistics of unemployment, returns of boards 
 of charity, court records of evictions, and pauper burials. What- 
 ever the actual figures may be, they would doubtless be startling 
 in comparison with statistics of our industrial progress. 
 
 Causes of Poverty and Riches. The explanations of poverty 
 and riches may be divided into two classes : (i) those that empha- 
 size individual responsibility, and (2) those that emphasize social 
 responsibility. According to the first, a comfortable fortune is the 
 reward of efficiency, and poverty the penalty of inefficiency. To 
 find fault with existing wealth distribution, it is alleged, is to find 
 fault with nature for making individual differences in ability so 
 enormous. That there are idle and worthless persons among the 
 rich is not to be denied, but they, it is said, are to be regarded as 
 the exceptions. As a class, according to this view, the rich add 
 more to the wealth of society than they consume, and they do not 
 in reality deduct anything from the income of the lower classes. 
 
 Those who emphasize the second explanation, on the other hand, 
 point to the existence of all sorts of special privileges which enable
 
 342 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the few to levy toll on the commerce of the nation. They assert 
 that the fortunes of most millionaires originated under the shelter 
 of some monopolistic enterprise. As to the poor, they call atten- 
 tion to the fact that inefficiency may be the result of poverty as 
 well as the cause of it. Society must, therefore, take active meas- 
 ures to better the environment of the poor. They must be taught 
 to live wisely, and their children must be given a fair chance in life. 
 Children who do not get enough to eat when young cannot be ex- 
 pected to take care of themselves when they are men and women. 
 
 "The prime importance of monopoly privileges in the distribution of 
 wealth is shown by the results of the investigation of the New York Tribune 
 (1892) in its efforts to ascertain the sources of the fortunes of the millionaires 
 of the United States. That investigation was undertaken to show that the 
 system of protection has not been the main cause for monopolies and great 
 fortunes. The investigation amply demonstrated this proposition. Of 
 the 4047 millionaires reported, only 1125, or 28 per cent, obtained their 
 fortunes in protected industries. The following partly estimated summaries 
 are based on the Tribune report. They show that about 78 per cent of the 
 fortunes were derived from permanent monopoly privileges and only 21.4 
 per cent from competitive industries unaided by natural and artificial monopo- 
 lies. Yet there can be no question that if these 21.4 per cent were fully 
 analyzed, it would appear that they were not due solely to personal abili- 
 ties unaided by these permanent monopoly privileges. They were mostly 
 obtained from manufactures, and five sixths of the manufactures of the 
 country are based on patents. Besides, fortunate investments in real estate, 
 stocks, etc., have often contributed to fortunes where they do not appear 
 prominently. Furthermore, if the size of the fortunes is taken into account, 
 it will be found that perhaps 95 per cent of the total values represented 
 by these millionaire fortunes is due to those investments classed as land 
 values and natural monopolies and to competitive industries aided by such 
 monopolies." * 
 
 Those who take this second view do not deny that individual 
 differences in ability exist and are a cause for a difference in for- 
 tune. But they think that conditions are such that differences in 
 reward are quite out of proportion to the difference in ability. A 
 little shrewdness may accumulate a fortune just as the touch of a 
 child's hand may start a bowlder down the mountain side. 2 
 
 The controversy as to the ultimate responsibility for poverty 
 
 1 Commons, The Distribution of Wealth, p. 252. 
 
 2 The relation of competitive wages to efficiency is discussed in Chapter XXII.
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 343 
 
 cannot be settled by an appeal to the results of the investigations 
 that have been made as to the immediate causes of poverty. The 
 investigation in the city of York, before referred to, gives the fol- 
 lowing as to the immediate causes of primary poverty, that is, 
 where the income was insufficient to provide the minimum re- 
 quirements for physical efficiency even if wisely spent: 
 
 TABLE IV 
 IMMEDIATE CAUSES OF " PRIMARY " POVERTY l 
 
 PER CENT OF POPULATION 
 m POVERTY 
 
 Death of chief wage earner 
 
 Illness or old age of chief wage earner 
 
 Chief wage earner out of work 
 
 Irregularity of work ; 
 
 Largeness of family, i.e. more than four children . 
 In regular work but at low wages 
 
 S-" 
 2.31 
 
 2.83 
 22.16 
 51.96 
 
 1 Rowntree, Poverty, p. 120. 
 
 Is Greater Diffusion Possible? Most people agree that a 
 greater equality of possessions would be desirable if it could be 
 brought about without any confiscation of the real earnings of the 
 more efficient members of society. The idea of a leisure class 
 whose mission is to further culture without great contribution to 
 the production of what it consumes, does not find much favor in 
 this democratic age. The disadvantages of wide extremes in 
 wealth have been so often pointed out by social philosophers that 
 they need not be emphasized here. But those who believe that 
 the competitive system roughly apportions rewards according to 
 individual production will say that nothing can be done directly to 
 diffuse wealth. That each individual should bear the consequences 
 of his own conduct, they think is necessary as a discipline for the 
 race. " Give the children of the shiftless, by thoughtless charity 
 or various systems of poor relief, the right to eat the substance of 
 the efficient and the prudent, and you will soon lose both the
 
 344 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 capital and the morality under which that capital has been cre- 
 ated," l says a writer of this class. 
 
 Those, on the other hand, who think that something can and 
 should be done directly, question the possibility of discovering the 
 separate productivity of workers under modern complex indus- 
 trial conditions with any degree of exactness, and think there is 
 little danger of discouraging industry and thrift. If the highest 
 incomes were $100,000 per year, men would struggle just as hard 
 as they do now to get into the highest class. 
 
 If we take the view that something can be done to lessen the 
 extreme inequality in wealth distribution that exists at the present 
 time, it is necessary to formulate some programme of social re- 
 form. In framing such a programme it must be remembered, on 
 the one hand, that the right of private property is not an abso- 
 lute right. No one has a vested interest in that institution, and we 
 are at liberty to make such modification in the institution as will 
 contribute to the social welfare. For the present the measures here 
 advocated are not in the slightest danger of being carried so far as 
 to discourage that wealth-getting ambition which is considered by 
 many to be essential to progress. On the other hand, there is 
 danger of injuring by wrong methods the very persons whom it is 
 desirable to elevate. Indiscriminate charity may convert poverty 
 to pauperism. 
 
 "This distinction between the poor and the paupers may be seen every- 
 where. There are, in all large cities in America and abroad, streets and courts 
 and alleys where a class of people live who have lost all self-respect and 
 ambition, and who rarely if ever work, who are aimless and drifting, who like 
 drink and who have no thought for their children, and who live aimless and 
 contentedly on rubbish and alms. ... In our American cities, Negroes, 
 Whites, Chinese, Mexicans, Half-breeds, Americans, Irish, and others are 
 indiscriminately housed together in the same tenements and often in the 
 same rooms. The blind, the crippled, the consumptive, the aged, the 
 ragged ends of life; the babies, the children, the half -starved, underclad 
 beginnings in life, all huddled together, waiting, drifting. This is pauper- 
 ism. There is no mental agony here; they do not work sore; there is no 
 dread ; they live miserable, but they do not care. 
 
 " In these same cities, and indeed everywhere, there are great districts of 
 people who are up at dawn, who wash and dress, and eat breakfast, kiss 
 1 Hadley, Economics, p. 49.
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 345 
 
 wives and children, and hurry away to work or to seek work. The world 
 rests upon their shoulders ; it moves by their muscle ; everything would stop 
 if for any reason they should decide not to go into the fields and factories and 
 mines. But the world is so organized that they gain enough to live upon 
 only when they work ; should they cease, they are in destitution and hunger. 
 The more fortunate of the laborers are but a few weeks from actual distress 
 when the machines are stopped. Upon the unskilled masses want is con- 
 stantly pressing. As soon as employment ceases, suffering stares them in 
 the face. They are the actual producers of wealth, but they have no home 
 nor any bit of soil which they can call their own. They are the millions who 
 possess no tools and can work only by permission of another. In the main 
 they live miserably, they know not why. They work sore, and yet gain noth- 
 ing. They know the meaning of hunger and the fear of want. They love 
 their wives and children. They try to retain their self-respect. They have 
 some ambition. They give to neighbors in need, yet they are themselves the 
 actual children of poverty." * 
 
 We shall not discuss here the methods of alleviating the suffer- 
 ing that comes from poverty. The best methods of charitable 
 relief are necessary as palliatives, but they cannot cure the evils of 
 poverty. Two classes of reform measures should be distinguished : 
 (i) those that aim to alter the methods of wealth acquisition in the 
 future, and (2) those that aim to diffuse the excessive accumu- 
 lations of the past. 
 
 Modifying the Methods of Wealth Acquisition. These methods 
 again fall into two classes : (a) prevention of improper methods of 
 wealth accumulation; (b) eliminating or strengthening the in- 
 efficient members of society. Under the first of these falls the 
 problem of reducing to lower terms such incomes as are indi- 
 vidually unearned. There must be such control of monopolistic 
 privileges as to keep them from being the means of exploiting the 
 masses. Fraud and favoritism must be eliminated so that income 
 shall not be wholly out of proportion to service or needs. 
 
 The second class includes a large variety of methods, (i) It is 
 possible to do something to prevent defective human beings from 
 being born. There is a growing sentiment in favor of preventing 
 the marriage of persons who are not fit for marriage. No indi- 
 vidual would be deprived of any important right if a medical cer- 
 tificate of good health were made a condition precedent to the 
 
 1 R. Hunter, Poverty, pp. 3-5.
 
 346 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 granting of a marriage license. (2) Education should be made 
 compulsory with the endeavor of making the rising generation 
 not only efficient producers of wealth, but also wise spenders of 
 what they receive. (3) It is possible to provide against the mis- 
 fortunes of life by insurance of various kinds. If men will not 
 voluntarily make provision for themselves and for those dependent 
 upon them in cases of sickness, accident, old age, and premature 
 death, they should be helped to do so indirectly by some com- 
 prehensive system of workingmen 's insurance and old age pen- 
 sions. (4) The solution of the problem of unemployment depends 
 upon more indirect measures, such as monetary and banking 
 reform, which steady the progress of industry, although European 
 experiments show that there are possibilities in insurance against 
 unemployment. (5) Opportunities for saving should be multi- 
 plied. The establishment of postal savings banks would be of 
 some assistance. (6) The health and vigor of the people should 
 be improved by sanitation and by legislation which improves the 
 conditions of work. 
 
 The Diffusion of Wealth. To some extent large fortunes dis- 
 appear without governmental interference, but it takes com- 
 paratively slight ability to maintain an inherited estate. It does 
 not seem practicable or desirable to limit directly the total amount 
 of wealth which a man may own, but there is no reason why the 
 government should refrain from consciously encouraging the dif- 
 fusion of wealth. The regulation and taxation of inheritances 
 seems to be the proper remedy in this connection, even if its action 
 is somewhat slow. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Can anything be said in favor of a leisure class? 
 
 2. Would Mr. Carnegie's plan of levying an inheritance tax of 50 per 
 cent destroy the incentive to work? 
 
 3. Explain the various systems of poor relief. 
 
 4. Describe the German system of compulsory insurance. 
 
 5. Describe the old age pension system in Australia. 
 
 6. What objections have been offered against postal savings banks ? 
 
 7. Discuss the following statement : " We have, then, little reason for 
 expecting that the prevailing insecurity in the lot of the modern workman 
 will ever be removed by the development of individual thrift." A. S. JOHN- 
 SON, Political Science Quarterly, Vol. XXII, p. 244.
 
 THE PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 347 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ADAMS, T. S., and SUMNER, H. L. Labor Problems, Chap. V. 
 
 BROOKS, J. G. The Social Unrest, Chap. VII. 
 
 BOOTH. Life and Labour of ttie People in London, final volume. 
 
 CANNAN, EDWIN. "Division of Income," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 
 
 Vol. 19, p. 341. 
 
 COMMONS, J. R. Distribution of Wealth, pp. 252 sqq. 
 DEVINE, E. T. Principles of Relief. 
 
 ELIOT, C. W. " Great Riches," World's Work, Vol. n, p. 7451. 
 ELY, R. T. Evolution of Industrial Society, Chap. VI, Part I. 
 HADLEY, A. T. Economics, pp. 39-63 and 330-335. 
 HUNTER, ROBERT. Poverty. 
 HOBSON J. A. The Social Problem, Chap. IV, and Problems of Poverty, 
 
 Chap. IX. 
 
 HENDERSON, C. R. Modern Methods of Charity. 
 JOHNSON, A. S. "Influences affecting the Development of Thrift," Political 
 
 Science Quarterly, Vol. XXII, No. 2. 
 LONDON, JACK. The People of the Abyss. 
 
 LAUGHLIN, J. L. "Large Fortunes," Atlantic Monthly, Vol. 96, p. 40. 
 MALLOCK, W. H. " Great Fortunes and the Community," North American 
 
 Review, Vol. 183, p. 349. 
 
 Paupers in Almshouses, 1904. Special Report of the Bureau of the Census. 
 ROWNTREE. Poverty, A Study in Town Life. 
 SPARGO, JOHN. Socialism, Chap. V. 
 
 SPAHR, C. B. The Present Distribution of Wealth in the United States. 
 SEAGER, H. R. Outline of a Program of Social Reform, Charities and 
 
 the Commons, February 2, 1907. 
 WARNER, A. G. American Charities. 
 WATKINS, G. B. "The Growth of Large Fortunes," Publications of the 
 
 American Economic Association, November, 1907. 
 YOUNGMAN, ANNA. "The Fortune of John Jacob Astor," Journal of 
 
 Political Economy, June, 1908.
 
 CHAPTER XXI 
 THE RENT OF LAND 
 
 RENT is the price paid for the services of land. In common 
 usage the meaning of the word is, however, much less exact. 
 That which one pays for the use of durable goods of any kind 
 owned by another is commonly called rent. The payment for 
 the use of a house or a business building is, for example, counted 
 as rent. We shall see that in this case the so-called rent really 
 consists of two elements, one a ground rent, or rent proper, the 
 other capital rent, or what we shall call gross interest. If this 
 distinction seems fanciful, it is only because we are accustomed 
 to see the two united under one ownership. But in most large 
 cities separate ownership is common. Sometimes one man owns 
 the land and leases it for a long term of years to another who 
 erects buildings upon it, which, either with or without payment, 
 become the property of the landowner at the expiration of the 
 lease, unless it is renewed, and if it is renewed, the one who pos- 
 sesses the building must frequently pay for it. Often, however, 
 the separation in ownership is a permanent one, the house owner 
 paying perpetually an annual sum for the use of the ground. 
 This is the case in Baltimore, for example, where ground rents 
 are an important feature in the economic life of the city. In 
 such cases the two kinds of income are very clearly distinguished. 
 
 Some modern economists have extended the meaning of both 
 rent and interest, using them as two different ways of describ- 
 ing one form of income, rather than as two distinct kinds of in- 
 come. This usage is based on the obvious fact that the rent 
 which a landlord receives for an acre of land may easily be com- 
 puted as a certain rate of interest on the money value of the land, 
 just as the amount earned by a machine may be viewed either 
 
 348
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 349 
 
 as the rent of the machine or as interest on its money value. 
 But we shall see later that the income from other production 
 goods, while governed in part by the same laws that control the 
 income from land, is also governed in part by very different laws. 
 Without dwelling further upon this distinction at this stage of 
 our discussion, let us remember that in the great majority of eco- 
 nomic writings the term " rent " means only an income from land, 
 and that it is used only in this sense in the following discussion. 
 The Services of Land. The first thing to be noted about 
 land is its quality. Differences of fertility are familiar to every one, 
 and depend upon what has been known as the "original and 
 indestructible properties of the soil." An effort has been made 
 by certain writers to minimize or deny the significance of this 
 factor. It has been said that " soil " is not indestructible, that 
 it may be exhausted or removed from land altogether, and that 
 it may in turn be created by means of fertilization. These writers 
 recognize in land no other indestructible property than standing 
 room. This objection arises from the use of the word " soil " in a 
 narrow sense. If by " soil " we mean only that thin top layer 
 containing some elements necessary to plant life, it is true that 
 this may be carted on or off at pleasure, that it may be wasted 
 or replenished. But, granting this, there still remain many 
 qualities of land which are indestructible and unproducible, 
 and which so directly affect the productiveness of the land that 
 we may not inappropriately call them "properties of the soil." 
 Such a property is the conformation of the land. A steep, grav- 
 elly hillside will by no possible effort equal a plain in fertility. 
 The north side of a mountain cannot be made to produce the 
 same as the south side. Climate is not, to be sure, a "property 
 of the soil," but it is an inseparable appurtenance of the land, 
 and upon it the productiveness of the land primarily depends. 
 It is needless to say that the ownership of a piece of land carries 
 with it the advantage of all the conditions which attach to that 
 land. It is simply true, therefore, that the expression "original 
 and indestructible properties of the soil" is an inadequate and 
 misleading expression; not that there is nothing but standing 
 room to be considered under such a term.
 
 35 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 We will, therefore, adopt another expression to explain what 
 we mean by quality in land; namely, the irremovable conditions 
 affecting its productiveness. Of these its extent (standing room), 
 its conformation, and its climate are essentially original and in- 
 destructible. Others, such as are connected with the " soil " in 
 the narrow sense, are not indestructible nor necessarily original, 
 but they affect rent none the less. In denning quality as the 
 conditions affecting productiveness of land, we have discarded 
 the word "soil" because it has proved itself treacherous; we 
 have omitted the words "original and indestructible" because 
 fertility may be artificial, and is always destructible. On the 
 other hand, fertility, even when artificial, becomes essentially a 
 property of the land. While it is physically removable, it is not 
 economically so. From the case where capital is embodied in 
 land and entirely assimilated to it in character, we pass by in- 
 sensible gradations to fences, barns, houses, etc., which more 
 and more assume the character of capital as distinguished from 
 land. It would be possible to restrict the term " land " to strictly 
 natural land, and apply the term " capital " to all products, in- 
 cluding the soils of old land. This would be a logical distinction, 
 but, like so many logical distinctions, it would be confusing. On 
 the other hand, if we include under land all capital that has been 
 incorporated in it, we must recognize that there is no absolute 
 line of division between land and capital. Thus we are again 
 reminded that distinctions in economics, as well as in practical 
 life, are questions of convenience, and are good or bad according 
 as they are more or less useful. 
 
 The second great fact regarding land is location. On one side 
 this is closely connected with climate. Land situated near a 
 body of water or near a mountain range is much affected by 
 these great controllers of climate. But a more distinct meaning 
 of the word is location with regard to the consumers of products. 
 Everybody knows that land a hundred miles from market is, 
 other things being equal, worth more than land a thousand miles 
 from market. This, however, is a question of accessibility rather 
 than of mere distance. Land may be far away and yet easy to 
 reach, or near and difficult of access. It will be noted that any
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 
 
 35' 
 
 change in the cost of transportation affects rents. The rents of 
 England have been revolutionized by cheap ocean transporta- 
 tion, which has practically brought distant land very near to her 
 shores. To this fact of location we must ascribe almost wholly 
 the enormous rents paid for city lots. Here, again, transporta- 
 tion facilities, such as are afforded by good rapid transit systems, 
 powerfully affect rents. 
 
 One important difference in the way quality and location affect 
 rent must, however, be noted. The quality of a piece of land 
 affects the amount of its physical product; it determines how 
 many bushels of wheat or how many pounds of cotton it will 
 yield with a given amount of cultivation. The location of land 
 does not, it is true, affect the amount of its physical product, 
 but it does affect the price of the product, since that varies with 
 the expense of transporting the product to market. The value 
 of a piece of land to the user depends upon the value of its yield, 
 which is ascertained by multiplying the number of units of prod- 
 uct by the price per unit. Suppose a man owns two wheat farms 
 of equal size, one in Dakota and one in Illinois. If the farm in 
 Dakota produces thirty bushels of wheat to the acre, and it costs 
 twenty cents a bushel to get it to the Chicago market, where wheat 
 is selling at a dollar per bushel, while the farmer in Illinois pro- 
 duces twenty-five bushels to the acre, and it costs four cents a 
 bushel to get this to the Chicago market, the farms are equally 
 productive so far as the owner is concerned, for in each case he 
 will get $24 for an acre's yield of wheat. If the other conditions 
 of production are the same, the farms are equally valuable to the 
 owner. Prom the social point of view, too, one of the farms is 
 as good as the other. For the costs of transportation, of moving 
 things to where they are wanted, have to be counted among the 
 legitimate and necessary costs of production. In short, we may 
 say that the two pieces of land are equally good land. When we 
 speak of good land, therefore, in connection with the subject of 
 rent, we mean land which for all purposes taken together is de- 
 sirable. 
 
 Rent under Assumed Conditions of Uniform Intensivity of 
 Cultivation. The first settlers in a new countrv have no need to
 
 35 2 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 pay rent. They find plenty of land, and even the best of it will be 
 a free good, like air or water. So long as any man can get land 
 of the best quality free, there is no reason why he should pay rent 
 to any one else. But this fortunate state of affairs will last only 
 so long as some of the best lands remain unoccupied. When 
 increase in the population makes the utilization of inferior lands 
 necessary, the owners of the better lands will be able to demand 
 and receive a rent for the use of their lands. This will be made 
 clear by reference to Figure i, which is constructed on the assump- 
 
 C D 
 
 FIG. i 
 
 F 
 
 tion that there are six grades of land, A, B, C, D, E, and F, and 
 that for all these lands the same amount of cultivation per acre 
 is necessary. The successive rectangles represent the selling 
 value of the product that can be raised on one acre of each of 
 these different grades of land, by the use of a fixed amount of 
 labor and capital. The product of an acre of the best land, A, 
 will sell for Oamy dollars. Until all of this best land is occupied, 
 no rent will be paid, and the entire value of the product will be 
 available for the expense of the capital and the wages of labor 
 employed in its cultivation. 1 
 
 As soon, however, as it becomes necessary to cultivate some of 
 the B lands, the situation will be altered. The owners of the A 
 lands can now exact a rent for their use, and the farmer has no 
 
 1 The profits which the farmer may receive as entrepreneur do not affect th? 
 analysis, and may accordingly be neglected.
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 353 
 
 alternative, except to utilize land of the second grade, on which 
 the fixed amount of labor and capital will only produce a prod- 
 uct per acre selling for abnk dollars. The rent which will be 
 charged per acre for A lands will amount to the difference between 
 the value of the products of the two grades of land (hkmy in the 
 diagram). For if the landowners attempt to charge more than 
 this difference, the farmers will find it more advantageous to use 
 the B lands; if they charge less, the A lands will be the more 
 remunerative to the farmer, and competition among the farmers 
 for the leases of A lands will force the rent up. In short, rent 
 will normally be fixed at the point which will just equalize the 
 advantages of cultivating the two kinds of land. 
 
 As soon as increased population and the consequent need of 
 a larger food supply and more raw materials have forced men to 
 begin to cultivate lands of the C grade, the B lands will command a 
 rent, while the rent of the A lands will be increased by an amount 
 equal to the rent of the B lands. And as cultivation is pushed 
 down to still poorer and poorer lands, the rents which these better 
 lands command will be still further increased. Thus, when some 
 lands of grade E are in use, the value of the product which can 
 be got from this free land, by the use of the fixed amount of labor 
 and capital, will be dert dollars per acre. This sum will just pay 
 the cost of labor and capital, for if it amounts to less than these 
 expenses of production, the E lands will not be worth cultivating; 
 if it amounts to very much more, it will pay to cultivate still poorer 
 land. But if dert dollars will just pay wages and interest on the 
 E lands, the same amount will pay wages and interest on the 
 better lands, for we have assumed that the same amount of labor 
 and capital is used on each grade of land. The expense for labor 
 and capital will, therefore, be represented on each rectangle by 
 the area below the line gt, while the area above this line will rep- 
 resent in each case the rent per acre which the landowner will 
 receive. 
 
 Rent, under these conditions, is a differential which measures 
 accurately the superiority of the rent-bearing land over the mar- 
 ginal land the land which just repays the expenses of cultiva- 
 tion. It is not necessary to the significance of the theory that
 
 354 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 all, or even any, of the farmers should be tenant farmers. If 
 the farmer owns the land that he operates, the part of his income 
 which measures the superiority of his land over an equal area of 
 marginal land, must, in any accurate analysis, be counted as rent. 
 Rent under Actual Conditions. The conditions assumed in 
 the foregoing analysis depart from actual conditions in one im- 
 portant particular, the assumption that equal amounts of labor 
 and capital, that is, a uniform intensivity of cultivation, would 
 be applied to lands of different grades. As a matter of fact, even 
 after the A lands are all occupied, the supply of agricultural prod- 
 ucts can be increased without resort to poorer lands. All that is 
 really necessary is the more intensive cultivation of the A lands. 
 This cannot be done, however, without encountering the law of 
 diminishing productivity. Successive equal amounts of labor 
 and capital used on the same lands cannot be expected to vield 
 uniformly large increments of product. It will pay, however, 
 to make use of more intensive cultivation up to the point where 
 the last unit of labor and capital adds barely enough to the prod- 
 uct to pay for the increased expense, a point which is called 
 the intensive margin. The result of this more intensive culti- 
 vation is represented in Figure 2. 
 Now the first rectangle in this dia- 
 gram (Oamy) represents precisely 
 the same thing as is represented by 
 the first rectangle in Figure i, the 
 return (in value of product) from 
 the cultivation of an acre of land 
 P of A grade by the use of a fixed 
 amount of labor and capital. The 
 second rectangle in Figure 2, how- 
 ever, represents the additional 
 product resulting from the use of a 
 similar unit of labor and capital on 
 the same acre, while the third rep- 
 resents the increment of product due to the employment of yet a 
 third unit of labor and capital on the same land. Assume that 
 this third unit, A^ adds just enough to the selling value of the 
 
 At 
 
 FIG. 2
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 
 
 355 
 
 product to pay for itself. Then, as already explained in the 
 discussion of diminishing productivity, the area Ocph will represent 
 that part of the farmer's income which will be used up by the 
 expense incurred for the three units of labor and capital used on 
 this one acre of land, and the area above the line hq will repre- 
 sent the real rent of that acre. If land E (Figure i) just repays 
 the expenses of cultivation when one unit of labor and capital 
 is used per acre, the value of the product per acre of this land 
 will equal the value of the increment of product attributable to 
 the third unit of labor and capital used on land A. (That is, the 
 area dcrt, Figure i, equals the area bcpq, Figure 2.) So far, 
 then, as the margin of cultivation is concerned, Figure i repre- 
 sents the conditions accurately. The productivity of capital and 
 labor at the intensive and extensive margins are the same. But 
 Figure i does not represent the complete theory of rent in that 
 (i) it does not indicate the fact that larger quantities of capital 
 and labor are used on the better lands than on the poorer lands, 
 and (2) it does not represent the larger products due to this 
 more intensive cultivation of the better lands. These considera- 
 tions are taken account of 
 in Figure 3, which also, by 
 the substitution of curves 
 for successive rectangles, 
 represents the infinite vari- 
 ety of degrees of goodness 
 of the different acres mak- 
 ing up the land supply of 
 a country. In Figure 3 
 the line am represents the 
 value of a product of a unit 
 of labor and capital on the 
 poorest land in use, and the 
 area hmi represents what FIG. 3 
 
 rent would be under con- 
 ditions of uniform intensivity of cultivation. The area Oamg 
 represents the diminishing amounts of labor and capital used 
 per acre as we pass from the better to the poorer lands, while the
 
 356 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 area ymg represents the rent per acre of the different grades of 
 lands. The foregoing analysis leads to the following statement 
 of the theory of rent, which the reader may verify for himself by 
 referring to Figures i and 2 : 
 
 The rent of any piece of land is measured by the difference between 
 the value of the products obtained from it by the use of the most profit- 
 able amounts of labor and capital and the value of the products 
 which could be obtained by the use of the same amounts of labor and 
 capital on marginal land, or at the intensive margin of cultivation. 
 
 This statement should not be understood as comparing the 
 total product raised on a given piece of land with the total product 
 which could be got from the same amount of marginal land. 
 This would be to reintroduce the assumption of uniform inten- 
 sivity of cultivation an assumption which impaired the ade- 
 quacy of the theory of rent illustrated in Figure i above. On the 
 contrary, it is assumed in the present statement that the farmer 
 would use whatever amount of the marginal land he found most 
 profitable. If it were profitable to use twenty times as much 
 labor and capital on a certain piece of land as on a similar amount 
 of marginal land, to employ the same amount of labor and capi- 
 tal profitably on marginal land would take twenty times as much 
 land. 
 
 Rent and the Marginal Product of Land. In an earlier chapter it was 
 suggested that rent could be measured by the marginal product of land ; in 
 other words, that the amount which a farmer would pay per acre for the use 
 of land would depend upon the value of so much of his product as was depend- 
 ent upon the possession of any one acre of land. In that discussion it was 
 assumed, however, that land was of a uniform degree of goodness. Obviously, 
 if all land really were of a uniform degree of goodness, in all ways equally 
 desirable, no rent would be paid until all lands were utilized, when rent would 
 arise on account of the necessity of increased intensivity of cultivation. 
 
 But even under the actual conditions of the existence of different grades of 
 land and of a large body of land which is below the margin of cultivation, 
 the rent of any acre of the better lands can be stated in terms of the value 
 of its product. For the rent of any acre of land is measured by the value of 
 the amount of the product imputed to it (as distinct from the product imputed 
 to the labor and the capital employed upon it). Now the product that must 
 be imputed to any acre of land is, of course, the amount which it adds to the 
 total product, or, what amounts to the same thing, the amount by which the
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 357 
 
 total product would be decreased if just as much labor and capital were em- 
 ployed in agriculture, but if this particular acre of land were not available. 
 This means, however, that the labor and capital which would have been 
 employed on this land would have to be utilized either in cultivating the lands 
 already utilized more intensively or in cultivating lands previously unculti- 
 vated; that is, at either the intensive or extensive margin. Obviously 
 the product imputed to the land in question would be the difference between 
 the total product got from it and the product 'which would result from the 
 employment of the same amount of labor and capital at the margin. Thus, by 
 a somewhat different line of analysis, we have again reached the statement 
 of the theory of rent given in the preceding section. 
 
 The Different Uses of Land. We have seen that' the better 
 lands will repay a more intensive cultivation than the poorer 
 lands, and have found this fact to be of great significance in the 
 theory of rent. By varying degrees of intensivity of cultivation 
 we do not mean only the more thorough cultivation of the land 
 in the raising of any one crop. Land produces a great variety 
 of products, and some of these need much more intensive culti- 
 vation than others. In the business of raising cattle, as it is con- 
 ducted on a large Western ranch, the total investment of capi- 
 tal and labor may be very considerable, but the investment per 
 acre of land is very small indeed, while a small market garden, 
 located near a great city, will repay a very high degree of inten- 
 sivity of cultivation. It is only on the best lands that crops neces- 
 sitating a large amount of labor per acre can be raised profitably. 
 By the best lands we mean in this connection not only those lands 
 which are best fitted by soil and climate for the production of 
 particular crops, but the best lands in the sense that they are 
 nearest the market. For example, cities in the eastern part of 
 the United States get part of their supply of fresh vegetables 
 from market gardens in their own environs, while another part 
 of this supply may come from the Southern states and even across 
 the continent from California. The local market gardens are 
 good lands on account of their situation; the more distant lands 
 are good lands on account of special qualities of soil or climate 
 which enable them to furnish "out of season" vegetables. 
 
 Because certain lands are adapted, on account of quality or 
 location, for intensive cultivation, they command high rents.
 
 358 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 On the other hand, lands which command high rents generally 
 have to be cultivated intensively, because the entrepreneur is 
 forced by the very fact of high rent to economize in his use of 
 land as compared with his use of capital and labor. The raising 
 of flax as raw material for linen is a profitable agricultural indus- 
 try in densely populated Belgium, but it has never met with much 
 success in the United States because flax straw of a quality fit for 
 the better grades of linen demands a large amount of care and 
 labor. Land is so plentiful here that it pays us better to special- 
 ize in a less intensive kind of agriculture to spread our labor 
 and capital more thinly over a larger number of acres. 
 
 The poorest land that can be profitably used in the growing 
 of any one kind of product is not necessarily marginal land. 
 Land too poor to use for market gardening may be good wheat 
 land; land too poor to devote to wheat may be good grazing land. 
 The poorest land devoted to any one purpose may yield a rent, 
 arising from its relative superiority for some other use. It will 
 be readily understood that the marginal lands used as a basis of 
 comparison in our statement of the law of rent are the poorest 
 lands used for any purpose grazing lands, possibly. But, as 
 we have seen, rent may also be measured from the intensive mar- 
 gin of cultivation, and the intensive margin is found on all 
 lands, even the best. 
 
 Although all our illustrations of the theory of rent have been 
 drawn from agriculture, the theory is, in fact, perfectly general. 
 The rent of land used for industrial or commercial purposes is 
 determined in precisely the same way as the rent of agricultural 
 land. In fact, different kinds of manufacturing, wholesale and 
 retail trading, quarrying, forestry, etc., may be looked upon as 
 different possible uses of land, differing in the amount of labor 
 and capital they require, and all subject to the law of diminish- 
 ing productivity, and hence to the law of rent. When we pass 
 from the agricultural uses of land to its commercial and indus- 
 trial uses, the fact of quality becomes of practically no importance 
 in the determination of rent, while the fact of location becomes 
 the fundamental one. 
 
 In addition to these different productive uses of land, we have
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 
 
 359 
 
 to take account of its other uses, such as for pleasure grounds and 
 residence sites. Here the explanation of rent is simpler than in 
 the case of productive lands. For these lands yield their utilities 
 directly, and hence come under the general law of value. Such 
 lands command a rent on account of their capacity to satisfy 
 human wants directly, the extent of this capacity being measured 
 by their marginal utility. In the case of productive lands, it is 
 only their products that satisfy human wants directly. The 
 lands themselves are valued according to the specific share of the 
 valuable product that can be imputed to their productivity, as 
 distinct from the productivity of labor and capital. 
 
 The Capitalization of Rent. To the individual who has a cer- 
 tain amount of money for which he is seeking the most profitable 
 use, the question whether he shall invest it in land or other form 
 of production goods is apt to be in itself an unimportant one. If 
 he chooses to buy land, it will be because he can get a satisfactory 
 income from it, and he will very properly count the income as 
 interest on the money he has invested in the land. If the income 
 from the land increases, the selling value of the land will increase. 
 From the point of view of our investor this will, of course, be an 
 increase in the "capital value" of the land. It is important to 
 note, however, that the land does not return an income simply 
 because it is valuable. The process is the reverse of this. The 
 land aids annually in the production of goods which command a 
 price in the market; a part of the value of this annual product is 
 imputed to the service of land and paid for in the form of eco- 
 nomic rent; and the land is valued because it commands a rent. 
 The value of the land is governed by its income-yielding power. 
 
 This fundamental fact is apt to escape our notice because in the 
 United States lands are more commonly sold than rented, so that 
 we think of the value of lands as the prices at which they will sell, 
 rather than their annual value, or rent, although the first kind of 
 value is derived from the second. In England, where lands are 
 more commonly rented, the value of land is usually thought of as 
 its annual value or rent, while the selling value is often expressed 
 as "twenty (or other number of) years' purchase," meaning twenty 
 times the annual rent. The process by which the capacity to yield
 
 360 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 a certain annual income is made the basis for the determination 
 of a certain selling price is termed "capitalization." l In a coun- 
 try which is growing in population and wealth, and where land 
 rents are consequently increasing, the selling value of land is apt 
 to be somewhat greater than a capitalization of the amount of 
 income it is yielding at the time of the sale would justify. This 
 is because the ownership of land carries with it the right to receive 
 future as well as present incomes, and the prospectively larger 
 future incomes are taken into account in the process of capitali- 
 zation. 
 
 Rent and Social Progress. The fact just mentioned the 
 tendency of rents to increase as society progresses is of very 
 great significance. It springs from the impossibility of satisfy- 
 ing the increasing wants of a society which is growing in popu- 
 lation and wealth without increasing the supply of food products 
 and raw materials by means of more extensive and more intensive 
 cultivation. As this means pushing downward the extensive and 
 intensive margins of cultivation, the necessary result is a rise in 
 rents. 
 
 During the early years of the nineteenth century the Napole- 
 onic wars on the continent, together with a high protective tariff 
 in England, kept England from importing any grain from Europe. 
 This, coupled with a considerable increase in the population of 
 England, resulted in very high prices for wheat, a rapid extension 
 of cultivation, and a remarkable rise in rents. It was the effort 
 on the part of economic writers to explain these facts that led to 
 the formulation of the theory of rent in substantially its present 
 form. Bound up with this theory of rent was the law of dimin- 
 ishing returns the name usually given to the statement that 
 the supply of agricultural products cannot be increased except 
 by the utilization of poorer and poorer lands, and consequently 
 at an increasing expense per unit of product. (This law should 
 
 1 The nature of this process of capitalization will be discussed in the chapter 
 on Interest. It is a fact of common observation that the rate of capitalization, 
 that is, the ratio of income to selling value, is lower in the case of land than in the 
 case of most forms of capital goods. The durability of land, the variety of uses 
 to which it may be put, and the social prestige attached to land ownership are 
 among the things that account for this.
 
 THE RENT O LAND 361 
 
 not be confused with the law of diminishing productivity. One 
 is a statement of a historical tendency in one form of produc- 
 tion agriculture; the other relates to the proportions in which 
 the factors of production are combined, and holds true for all 
 forms of production.) 
 
 This law of diminishing returns has been made the basis of 
 many gloomy prophecies regarding the possibilities of a general 
 and continued economic progress. Especially when this theory 
 was combined with the Malthusian theory of population, which 
 was based on the belief that population would tend to increase 
 as fast as the food supply would permit, did it seem to point to 
 insuperable barriers in the way of any considerable progress in 
 human welfare. 
 
 The history of the past century has belied these gloomy prophe- 
 cies. The increase in population has been greater than in any 
 previous period of the world's history, and yet, so far as agricul- 
 tural lands are concerned, the general level of rents has not in- 
 creased. In fact, the change has been in the other direction. 
 That rents have not increased as population has grown, does not 
 disprove the law of diminishing returns. That law, like other 
 economic laws, is true only as a statement of a tendency. If 
 this tendency has not resulted in increased rents, it is not because 
 it has not been operative, but because other powerful factors 
 have counteracted its effects. Two things, at least, have pre- 
 vented a rise in rents. In the first place, improvements in agri- 
 cultural methods have greatly increased the product which can 
 be got from a given acre of land. We must include here not only 
 improvements in methods of tillage and cultivation, in fertilizers, 
 in the varieties of plants, in breeds of live stock, etc., but also 
 organized social methods looking toward a better utilization of 
 the nation's land supply, such as the irrigation of dry lands, and 
 scientific forestry, which latter has an important influence upon 
 the conservation of the rainfall. 
 
 Of much greater importance, however, than all these things 
 taken together, has been the revolution in ocean and land trans- 
 portation, which has so largely increased the available amount 
 of land. Lands in England have gone out of cultivation because
 
 362 OUTLINES' OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the railway and the steamship have brought the great wheat fields 
 of America to her very doors. Even in the United States the new 
 lands brought near to market by the railways have often been of 
 better quality than the lands previously cultivated, so that the 
 margin of cultivation has gone up rather than down. There were 
 2,250,000 acres of improved farming lands in the state of New 
 Hampshire in 1850; by 1900 this acreage had shrunk to 1,075,000. 
 In Massachusetts the improved farm lands decreased in this period 
 of fifty years from 2,135,000 acres to 1,300,000 acres. Similar 
 figures could be given for others of the older states. The dimi- 
 nution in the use of old lands may be partly accounted for by 
 their deterioration in fertility under continual cultivation without 
 proper rotation of crops. But this is only a partial explanation, 
 for any one who is familiar with the conditions knows that even 
 the most careful tillage could not have kept millions of acres of 
 farm land which were once rent-yielding from going below the 
 margin of cultivation, for the simple reason that the margin of 
 cultivation rose. The railway practice of making very much lower 
 rates per mile on long hauls than on short hauls has hastened this 
 process, by minimizing the disadvantages of lands of good qual- 
 ity situated at a distance from the market. 
 
 The fact that since the introduction of the railway the margin 
 of cultivation has risen does not mean that it has risen continu- 
 ously, or that it will continue to rise. There are many who be- 
 lieve that we have only gained a brief and already passing respite 
 from the day when every increase in the demand for food products 
 and raw materials will be met only with increasing difficulty. 
 It is as dangerous to prophesy, however, as it was a hundred years 
 ago. The fact that there still remain some unutilized lands of 
 good quality in what are now out-of-the-way parts of the world 
 may prove to be of less importance than other things. It is a 
 striking fact that in the United States to-day only about half of 
 the land actually in farms is cultivated. Some of these unculti- 
 vated portions of farms are very poor lands, and others are given 
 over to meadows and pastures. But we venture to say that this 
 idle acreage is due in part to a lack of correspondence between 
 the historical conditions that have fixed the size of farms and the
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 363 
 
 economic conditions that fix the number of acres that can be 
 profitably utilized by one farmer. This unexploited area is, to 
 that extent at least, a reserve which can be drawn upon as the 
 demand for agricultural products increases. Then, too, we are 
 just beginning to have some idea of the improvements which 
 scientific selection may bring about in the qualities and produc- 
 tiveness of different kinds of plants; methods of fertilization and 
 tillage are still the subjects of fruitful scientific inquiry; forestry 
 and irrigation are yet in their infancy. Changes in demand, of 
 such a nature as to make possible the utilization of some lands for 
 the production of crops for which they are better fitted than for 
 their present uses, are also among the things that may resist the 
 tendency toward a general rise in rents. In fact, although it is 
 absurd to suppose that the rent of land will not increase as society 
 continues to increase in wealth and numbers, it is just as absurd 
 to make this fundamental tendency toward diminishing returns 
 in agriculture a basis for pessimistic views regarding the possi- 
 bility of economic progress. 
 
 The Unearned Increment. When we say that the margin of 
 cultivation has gone up, rather than down, since 1850, we do not 
 imply that rents have not, in many cases, increased. The new 
 lands opened up to use by new railways, for example, are at first 
 very cheap lands, often free lands. As they are taken up, they 
 command higher and higher rents. Practically all of the agri- 
 cultural lands now utilized in America have had such a history, 
 even though in some cases the present rents are not as high 
 as their rents at some previous time. The fact that, through the 
 change in transportation methods, the marginal farming lands 
 of to-day are better lands than the marginal farming lands of sixty 
 years ago does not affect the fact that the sum total of land rents, 
 and consequently of land values, is immensely greater to-day than 
 at any previous time. The increase in the value of land which 
 accompanies the increase in its income-yielding power is often 
 called the unearned increment. This phrase suggests that the in- 
 crease in land values cannot be attributed to any special effort 
 on the part of the owners of land, but is due to general social 
 causes.
 
 364 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 This does not mean that the land-owning farmer cannot increase 
 the selling value of his farm by wise investments of capital; but, 
 remembering that rent is the payment for the irremovable con- 
 ditions affecting the productiveness of land, it is clear that it can 
 be affected only to a comparatively small degree by the efforts 
 of individual landowners. Most of the present values of lands 
 have grown out of that complex of things which we call general 
 social progress, the most important of which in this connection 
 are growth in population and growth in average wealth the 
 things that lead to an increased demand for the products of the 
 soil. Nor is the truth of this statement affected by the fact that 
 the opening of new lands has been among the most powerful fac- 
 tors that have made possible this growth in population and wealth. 
 A very large part of the increase in land values would have come 
 about, even if the use of land and the ownership of land were 
 entirely distinct, if all lands were leased, rather than owned, by the 
 users of land. We should, however, be careful to distinguish the 
 rise in the sum total of rents which springs from the occupation 
 of new and often better lands, and the increase in rent per acre, 
 which comes from forcing downward the margin of cultivation. 
 
 Some writers have suggested that landowners do not secure 
 an unearned increment, because future as well as present earning 
 power is taken account of in fixing the price at which land is 
 bought. But whether the selling value of land is based on its 
 present or future earning capacity, this selling value will increase 
 so long as the earning capacity of the land increases, and so long 
 as the increase in earning capacity promises to continue into the 
 future. An unearned increment is attached to valuable land, 
 whether it is still in the hands of the original owner, who may 
 have got it for nothing, or whether its ownership has been trans- 
 ferred a hundred times. Most economists have seen in the un- 
 earned increment a fact of very great social significance, and some 
 have even supported various plans by which some of the unearned 
 value might be returned to society through special taxation. 
 
 An American reformer, Henry George, converted a large following to his 
 view that all taxes should be levied upon land values. This scheme, known 
 as the "single tax," proposes that economic rent shall go to the government
 
 THE RENT OF LAND 365 
 
 in lieu of taxes a proceeding which would amount to the government 
 ownership of land, and is so understood by its adherents. The merits and 
 defects of the single tax as a scheme for raising public revenue will be con- 
 sidered in another place. Here we are concerned with it simply as a scheme 
 of economic reform. Henry George's main argument was based on the alleged 
 tendency of land to absorb all the value due to "improvements in the pro- 
 ductive power of labor." Among these improvements in the productive 
 power of labor he included such diverse things as " the growth of population, 
 the increase and extension of exchanges, the discoveries of science, the march 
 of invention, the spread of education, the improvement of government," etc. 
 "Land being necessary to labor, and being reduced to private ownership, 
 every increase in the productive power of labor but increases rent the 
 price that labor must pay for the opportunity to utilize its powers, and thus 
 all the advantages gained by the march of progress go to the owner of land, 
 and wages do not increase." 
 
 In the first place, we may object strongly to the assumption that improve- 
 ments in methods of production necessarily mean improvements in the " pro- 
 ductive power of labor" an assumption which, like the socialists' labor 
 theory of value, really begs the whole question. It would be just as reason- 
 able to call these things improvements in the productive power of capital 
 or improvements in the productive power of land. In the second place, we 
 must enter an emphatic denial to the statement that "all the advantages 
 gained by the march of progress go to the owner of land." If the supply of 
 labor is increasing more rapidly than the supply of land, it is probable that 
 rent per acre will increase faster than wages per laborer; but this does not 
 preclude an advance in wages. 
 
 It must be remembered, too, that Henry George did not propose to abolish 
 rent, an obvious impossibility, but simply to do away with the private 
 receipt of rent. This would prevent the withholding of land from use for 
 purely speculative purposes; thus increase the available supply of land, 
 and consequently lower rents. That such would be the immediate result of 
 throwing all land open to use cannot be denied. But in the long run it would 
 probably have little effect on rent, as it would simply lead to a more rapid 
 exploitation of the land. Land ownership, like any other institution, has 
 to be judged from the broad viewpoint of social interests. The "pride of 
 ownership," as an incentive to accumulation and as a basis for good citizen- 
 ship, cannot be lightly put aside. 
 
 Urban Lands. The unearned increment is an especially sig- 
 nificant phenomenon in the case of urban lands. In the modern 
 city we have a tremendous mass of land values created by causes 
 that are purely social, being an absolutely necessary result of 
 the concentration of a large population on a relatively small
 
 366 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 area. 1 All are familiar with the narrow limits set upon the whole- 
 sale districts, the shopping districts, and the financial districts 
 in American cities. The residence districts to which the greatest 
 social prestige attaches are apt to be quite as narrowly restricted. 
 Improvements in rapid transit facilities enlarge the residence 
 areas that are utilized by people with moderate incomes, but only 
 serve to increase the congestion in the business centers. There 
 is much to be said in favor of the special taxation of city land 
 values. Movements in this direction have already gained great 
 strength in England and Germany. Taxes so heavy as to amount 
 to confiscation would, in the opinion of the present writers, be 
 unjustifiable, and, in the United States, unconstitutional. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Malthus and Ricardo differed as to whether rent is an addition to the 
 total income of society. What is the correct view ? 
 
 2. An accepted doctrine of taxation is that landowners cannot shift a tax 
 on land values to any one else (as the tax on tobacco is shifted from the 
 manufacturer to the consumer). Explain this on the basis of the theory 
 of rent. 
 
 3. "Rent does not enter into the determination of price." Explain the 
 meaning of this statement, understanding price to mean "normal value." 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. V. 
 
 GEORGE, HENRY. Progress and Poverty. 
 
 KURD, R. M. The Principles of City Land Values. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, Vol. I, 4th ed., Book VI, 
 
 Chaps. IX and X. 
 
 PIERSON, N. G. Principles oj Economics, Vol. I, Part. I, Chap. II. 
 RICARDO, DAVID. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Chap. II. 
 TAYLOR, H. C. Agricultural Economics, Chap. IX. 
 WALKER, F. A. Land and its Rent. 
 
 1 The assessed value of land, exclusive of improvements, in the city of New York, 
 amounted in 1907 to over three and a half billions of dollars an amount nearly 
 twice as great as the assessed value of all the real estate, including improvements, 
 in the state of New York outside of the city.
 
 CHAPTER XXII 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 
 
 WAGES constitute the price paid for the services of labor. Under 
 the head of " labor " we include all the various kinds of personal 
 services for which a payment is made. Professional men and 
 salaried employees are wage earners in the economic sense, though 
 the term is by common usage generally restricted to manual 
 laborers working for daily or weekly payments. There is how- 
 ever, in society to-day, as every one recognizes, a " laboring class," 
 marked off by lines that are fairly distinct, and including the great 
 body of day laborers, factory hands, agricultural laborers, men in 
 various trades requiring various degrees of intelligence and skill, 
 employees in minor positions in business and mercantile establish- 
 ments, and the like. Some of the most important and pressing 
 present-day economic problems the variety of things that make 
 up what is often called the " labor problem " relate to the eco- 
 nomic position of this class. On this account it becomes of special 
 importance to ascertain just what the rules are that determine 
 its share in the national dividend. In the discussion of wages, 
 then, we have in mind primarily the income of the " laboring 
 class," although some of the principles that will be developed 
 apply just as accurately to the other incomes that must be 
 classed as wages in the economic sense. 
 
 Wages as the Price of Labor. The definition of wages already 
 given suggests at once the most important fact about them: they 
 are the prices paid for particular kinds of services, and hence come 
 under the general laws of supply and demand. So far as the wages 
 of any one kind of labor are concerned, we can say, as we did of 
 the prices of commodities, that they will tend to be fixed at the 
 point where the supply of that kind of labor and the demand for 
 
 367
 
 368 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 it are in equilibrium. But, as was found in the discussion of the 
 prices of commodities, this simple statement does not take us very 
 far into the analysis of the problem. We want to know why the 
 supply of labor and the demand for it are what they are. We shall 
 find, too, that the factors governing the supply and demand of 
 labor are in some respects very different from those governing the 
 supply and demand of commodities. 
 
 The Demand for Labor. The demand for labor is, in the last 
 analysis, a demand for the products of labor. Labor does not 
 command a price on its own account, but because it aids in the 
 production of things that satisfy human wants. But how can we 
 measure the product of labor? How can we distinguish it from 
 the shares in the total product that are to be attributed to land and 
 capital ? We obviously cannot say that the product of labor is 
 to be measured by the difference between the total product pro- 
 duced by the cooperation of labor, land, and capital and the prod- 
 uct which would be produced by land, and capital working alone; 
 for this last would, of course, be zero. The fact is, as we have seen 
 in a previous chapter, that the proportion of the product that is 
 attributed to labor is determined by the principle of marginal 
 productivity. That is, we cannot think of the " product of labor," 
 except as the product of the individual laborers making up the 
 supply of labor, and the product of any individual laborer is ac- 
 tually and exactly the amount which he adds to the total product 
 of land, labor, and capital; in other words, the amount by which 
 the total product would be decreased if the labor of this individual 
 laborer were not utilized. The social demand for the products 
 of labor, which is the basis of the entrepreneur's demand for labor, 
 is not a demand for any vague abstraction like the " product of 
 labor in general," but is a demand for the concrete products due 
 to the activities of individual laborers. 
 
 We must note also that in the case of labor, as in the case of 
 commodities, the word " demand " must not be taken in a loose, 
 indefinite sense. The demand for commodities means the quan- 
 tities that will be taken at certain definite prices. The demand 
 for labor does not mean anything unless it is understood to refer 
 to the number of laborers that will be employed in a particular
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 369 
 
 occupation at a certain wage. In a given occupation at a particu- 
 lar time wages might be fixed at any one of a large number of dif- 
 ferent possible points. The higher the wage, the smaller will be 
 the number of laborers that an entrepreneur can afford to employ; 
 and that for two reasons: In the first place, the higher wages 
 mean higher expenses of production, and consequently higher 
 prices will have to be charged for the product a fact which will 
 reduce the quantity of the product that can be sold on the market, 
 and consequently reduce the demand for labor. In the second 
 place, higher wages for labor will induce entrepreneurs to econo- 
 mize in the use of labor, and to use relatively more land and 
 capital, according to the principles which have been explained 
 in the discussion of diminishing productivity. The demand for 
 any particular kind of labor is thus a complex factor, influenced 
 both by variations in the demand for the products of that particular 
 kind of labor, and in the proportions of the product that can be 
 attributed to labor rather than to land and capital. 
 
 In a similar way the elasticity of the demand for any kind of 
 labor the extent to which variations in wages will affect the 
 quantity of labor utilized is a complex function, being affected 
 not only by the elasticity of the demand for the particular products 
 produced by this kind of labor, but also by the readiness with 
 which more capital or more land, or both, can be substituted for 
 labor, as, labor becomes higher priced. In the printing industry, 
 for example, a rise in wages would make it profitable for employing 
 printers to use more labor-saving machinery, such as type-setting 
 and linotype machines, automatic press feeders, and the like. 
 The higher the wages of agricultural laborers, the more profitable 
 will be the more extensive, as compared with the more intensive, 
 uses of land. On the other hand, the reader will at once think 
 of many trades, such as plumbing, where machinery cannot be 
 substituted for hand labor, and where, consequently, the only 
 elastic element in the demand for labor lies in the elasticity of the 
 demand for the products of labor. 
 
 The Effect of Labor-saving Machinery on the Demand for Labor. In what 
 has just been said about the use of machinery as a substitute for labor, we 
 have had in mind only the effect of changes of wages on the relative amounts 
 2B
 
 370 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of labor and of capital that would be used in any one branch of production. 
 Quite another problem, and one of great social importance, relates to the way 
 in which the demand for labor is affected by new inventions and by the 
 introduction of new machine processes. The laborers themselves have often 
 looked at such innovations with hostility. When machinery first began to 
 be used extensively in the woolen industry in England, this opposition was 
 expressed in riots in which the new machines were destroyed, as well as in 
 " proposals to impose legislative restrictions on the use of machines, so as to 
 bring them to a level with hand work, and prevent them from doing the work 
 more quickly or more cheaply than it could be done by hand." l In many 
 cases laborers still are inclined to view the introduction of labor-saving 
 machinery as an economic injury to themselves. On the other hand, there 
 are many persons who claim that this attitude on the part of the laborers is 
 an evidence of shortsightedness, since the inevitable result of machine pro- 
 duction is to cheapen the prices of products and thus to lower the cost of 
 living, the net result being an increase in real wages, as contrasted with nominal 
 or money wages. 
 
 This view emphasizes an important truth, and yet it misses the real point 
 of the laborers' alleged grievance. It is true that while the first result of the 
 introduction of improved methods of production is often to bring larger profits 
 to those who introduce them (especially if the new methods are protected by 
 patents), their benefits are ultimately diffused throughout society at large in 
 the form of the fuller and better satisfaction of wants, and the laboring class, 
 as members of society, share in these advantages. But while it is thus true 
 that such improvements ultimately redound to the benefit of laborers as a 
 class, it is equally true that hardship to many individual laborers is often an 
 immediate result of the introduction of labor-saving machinery. Especially 
 is this true in the case of skilled workmen in highly specialized employments, 
 who sometimes find themselves suddenly deprived of the advantages of their 
 skill, gained often by long years of apprenticeship. To expect that such 
 men will feel that they are compensated for their personal loss by the advan- 
 tages ultimately accruing to laborers as a class, is to ask too much of the altru- 
 istic elements in human nature. Workmen have learned, however, from the 
 experience of the past hundred years, that the introduction of machinery is 
 inevitable, and in the better-organized trades they are in many cases pursuing 
 the wiser course of trying to regulate the conditions of the introduction of new 
 kinds of labor-saving machinery in such a way as to diminish the hardship in- 
 flicted on individual workingmen. Thus, when the linotype machine began to 
 displace hand compositors in the printing trade, the typographical union was 
 able to secure the retention of many hand compositors as linotype operators, 
 together with a reduction in the length of the working day. 
 
 It should be noted also that the effect of the introduction of machinery 
 upon the demand for labor varies in different industries, the most important 
 
 1 Cunningham and McArthur, English Industrial History, p. 226.
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 371 
 
 factor in this connection being the elasticity of the demand for the products 
 of the particular trade affected. In the case of the linotype just mentioned, 
 the lessened cost of composition made it possible for newspapers to increase 
 their reading matter greatly, so that the actual reduction in the number of 
 employees was small compared with what might have been expected. The 
 introduction of machine methods into the English texile industry during the 
 period of the Industrial Revolution furnishes an instructive example. The 
 change in the methods of manufacturing cotton cloth came just as the in- 
 vention of the cotton gin had greatly increased and cheapened the supply of 
 raw material. This, coupled with the decreased cost of manufacturing, so 
 cheapened cotton cloth (which had previously been very expensive) that its 
 use was largely increased. In fact, a great many more persons were employed 
 in spinning and weaving cotton soon after the Industrial Revolution than 
 immediately before it. In the woolen industry, however, there was no such 
 immediate increase in the sale of the product, so that many workers were 
 displaced, and had to seek occupations where their specialized skill was of no 
 avail. Especially when the occupation affected is a highly specialized but 
 relatively unimportant one in a series of processes comprised in the manufac- 
 ture of a product the wage-earning power of the displaced laborers is apt to 
 be seriously diminished. 
 
 The Supply of Labor. It is when we fix our attention upon the 
 nature of the supply of labor that differences between the way 
 in which wages are determined and the way in which the prices 
 of commodities are determined become most noticeable. In the 
 first place, if we view industry in general, we notice that in the case 
 of labor there cannot be much difference between the actual supply 
 and what we called, when discussing exchange value, the " po- 
 tential supply." Labor is in this particular like the most perish- 
 able of commodities: the number of working days in a man's 
 life is limited, and those that are not sold are irrevocably gone. 
 The laborer has, it is true, some power in the way of " holding 
 out for higher wages," but even this power is limited rather nar- 
 rowly by the absolute necessity of making a livelihood. In the 
 long run small wages are better than none. The sale of labor is 
 most often a forced sale. In the second place, the fact that labor 
 is inseparable from the person of the laborer has important results. 
 When the laborer enters into an agreement to work for wages, he 
 not only sells his labor, but he gives up a certain amount of control 
 over his own life ; he agrees to live and work under conditions 
 often unpleasant ones set for him by others ; he accepts, in
 
 372 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 short, all the environment of his task, as well as the task itself. 
 Connected to some extent with this last fact is a third difference 
 the relative immobility of labor. Commodities may always 
 be sent to the market where they will command the best price, 
 but the laborer is restrained by family ties, patriotism, differences 
 in language, customs, and religion, ignorance, and the like. The 
 result is that variations in wages as between different countries 
 or as between different localities in the same country are much 
 greater than similar variations in prices. 
 
 We are apt to take it for granted that the supply of labor in dif- 
 ferent countries and localities depends primarily on the numbers 
 of the population. This is, of course, fundamentally true, but we 
 must also note that the structure of the population is a variable 
 thing, and one that affects the supply of labor. Over four fifths 
 of the persons employed in gainful occupations in the United States 
 in 1900 were males a fact which suggests that the relative 
 proportions of the sexes in the population have an important effect 
 on the supply of labor. There are more males than females in 
 the population of the United States, while the reverse is true of 
 most European countries, this difference being due in large part 
 to the excess of males among our European immigrants. There 
 are important differences in this respect between the individual 
 states. Males constitute nearly two thirds of the population of 
 Montana and less than one half of the population of Massachusetts. 
 The age composition of the population must also be taken into 
 account. The United States census of 1900 showed that nine 
 tenths of the persons engaged in gainful occupations were between 
 15 and 65 years of age comprising what is sometimes called 
 the " productive age group." A larger proportion of the popu- 
 lation of the United States is between these ages than is the case 
 in most European countries a fact which is due to the large 
 number of foreign-born adults in our population. In most Euro- 
 pean countries a larger proportion of the population is of " pro- 
 ductive age " than is true for the native population of the United 
 States. In considering the effect of these natural groupings of 
 the population upon the supply of labor, we have to also take ac- 
 count of differences in the nature of industries, in national or local
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 
 
 373 
 
 customs, and in the presence or absence of legal restrictions, 
 all of which affect the number of women and children who can 
 be counted as part of the available supply of labor. Many ob- 
 servers have suggested that the frequent holidays found in the 
 Latin countries of Europe form an appreciable obstacle in the 
 way of the industrial development of those countries, as they 
 materially diminish the real supply of labor. 
 
 The supply of labor is not, however, merely a matter of the 
 number of available laborers; it is also conditioned by their effi- 
 ciency. The physical strength and vigor, industry, intelligence, 
 ingenuity, and moral qualities of the laboring population deter- 
 mine the amount and kinds of work they can do. These things 
 vary greatly as between different races and as between different 
 individuals of the same race. They are not entirely a matter of 
 heredity, for they can be influenced greatly by the physical and 
 social environment. So far as high wages mean more and better 
 food, and improve the other conditions of living, they tend to in- 
 crease physical and mental efficiency, and thus to increase the 
 quantity and better the quality of labor that can be got from a 
 given population. There may often be, even when we take only 
 production into account, a real economy in high wages. 1 Public 
 education and public activity in regard to such matters as pure 
 foods, hygienic conditions in homes and in factories, and oppor- 
 tunities for wholesome recreation tend to increase the efficiency of 
 labor, and might be justified on this ground. The right view, 
 however, is that such things would be justified on their own ac- 
 count, as tending to raise the level of human living, even if they 
 did not increase human efficiency. 
 
 The Relation of the Growth of the Population to the Supply of 
 Labor. Just as the potential supply of commodities at any given 
 time is determined largely by past conditions, so the potential 
 supply of labor at any given time is to a very large extent pre- 
 determined. Subject to the limitations which have been men- 
 
 1 It sometimes happens that a sudden decrease in wages acts as a spur or 
 stimulus, and thus increases, temporarily, the productive efficiency of labor. 
 This fact, which has been noted by many employers, does not affect the signifi- 
 cance of the relation between high wages and efficiency, when a longer period of 
 time is taken into account.
 
 374 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tioned in the preceding section, the supply of labor is a matter of 
 the numbers of the population, and the factors affecting the growth 
 of the population are, from the long-time point of view, the most 
 important things determining the supply of labor. Most of the 
 discussion of these factors has centered around the Malthusian 
 theory of population the doctrine that population tends to 
 increase faster than the food supply, and is only held back by the 
 actual pressure of famine and disease (arising from an insufficient 
 food supply) , or by the prudential motives which restrain men from 
 undertaking the responsibility of marrying and raising families 
 upon incomes insufficient to provide the necessities of life. Just 
 what the first part of this doctrine means can be made clear by 
 referring to the conditions in a country like India, where the popu- 
 lation presses so closely upon the food supply that any considerable 
 failure in the rice crop is sure to result in famine and starvation. 
 Every increase in the food supply is followed there by an increase 
 in the birth rate and a decrease in the death rate; every diminu- 
 tion in the food supply is followed by a decrease in the birth rate 
 and an increase in the death rate. The frequent famines in India, 
 which have been charged by some ignorant or prejudiced observers 
 to neglect or incompetence on the part of the British government, 
 are, in fact, absolutely unpreventable, so long as these conditions 
 prevail. When, however, we fix our attention upon the United 
 States, or England, or any country possessing Western civilization, 
 we notice some things that do not seem to harmonize with the 
 Malthusian theory. The population does not press so closely 
 upon the food supply that any widespread suffering follows a 
 season of poor crops. Poverty seems to have but little restrictive 
 effect on the birth rate, which is generally higher among the poorer 
 classes than among the well-to-do. Such facts have been cited 
 by critics of the Malthusian theory, some of whom have been 
 inclined to credit it with very little economic significance. Yet 
 when we take a broader view of the facts, they appear in quite a 
 different light. 
 
 The best estimates indicate that England did not have over 
 five and a half million inhabitants in 1630, and yet overcrowding 
 at home was one of the reasons commonly given for the policy
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 
 
 375 
 
 of colonization which England was undertaking at that time. A 
 hundred years later, despite the growth of industry, and of foreign 
 and domestic trade, as well as some important improvements in 
 agricultural methods, the population had increased to only about 
 6,200,000. In 1761, on the eve of the Industrial Revolution, the 
 population is estimated to have been about 6,7oo,ooo. 1 By 1831, 
 when the factory system was thoroughly established (although 
 England was still trying to raise most of her own food supply), 
 the population had more than doubled, amounting to about 
 14,000,000. Since that time England has developed her manu- 
 facturing and commercial interests, but has imported a larger and 
 larger proportion of her food supply and raw materials from newer 
 countries, where land is cheaper. The latest census of England 
 (1901) showed a population of 32,500,000. There is no explana- 
 tion of this remarkable growth in the population of a country 
 which was " overcrowded " in 1630, other than the obvious one 
 contained in the fact that the opening up of new countries and the 
 improvements in transportation have enormously increased the 
 world's supply of food products and raw materials a consider- 
 able portion of which England has been able to get for herself 
 through the development of those commercial and manufacturing 
 activities in which her early start, her situation, her coal and iron 
 mines, and her own necessities, have given her a preeminence. 
 
 The total population of all Europe in 1760 was probably not 
 over 130,000,000. In 1905 it was about 405,000,000, some 
 200,000,000 of this increase having taken place since 1820, and 
 about 100,000,000 since 1872. Account must also be taken of 
 about 100,000,000 persons of European origin or descent living 
 outside of Europe at the beginning of the twentieth century. 
 Moreover, wherever this European expansion has carried Western 
 civilization and industrial methods, the numbers of the native 
 population have more often increased than decreased. 2 Such, for 
 example, is the case in Mexico, South America, the Philippines, 
 Java, India, and Egypt. For at least a hundred and fifty years 
 
 1 For these estimates, see Census of Great Britain, 1850, Vol. II. 
 * W. F. Willcox, "The Expansion of Europe in its Influence upon Population," 
 in Studies in Philosophy and Psychology, by former students of C. E. Garman.
 
 376 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 before the opening of Japan to Western civilization its population 
 had remained nearly stationary. Since 1871 it has increased from 
 33,000,000 to approximately 50,000,000 (1908). The probability 
 that this great increase in that part of the world's population which 
 has adopted modern industrial methods has come about by a 
 decrease in the death rate rather than by an increase in the birth 
 rate does not alter the significance of the fact that these improved 
 methods of production and transportation have operated like the 
 release of a spring, 1 allowing the natural tendency toward the 
 increase of the population to work itself out more fully. 
 
 In view of these facts it is impossible to deny a large amount of 
 significance to the Malthusian theory of population. Population 
 has generally increased wherever the increase in wealth has 
 afforded it opportunity. Yet it does not follow that the Mal- 
 thusian theory is, in its strictest interpretation, true. Population 
 has not increased as rapidly as wealth has increased. Average 
 real incomes are very much higher than they were before the In- 
 dustrial Revolution a statement that holds true for average 
 real wages as a particular form of income. Interpreted in the 
 light of the theory of diminishing productivity, this means that 
 population has not increased so rapidly as capital and the avail- 
 able supply of land have increased. If there had been no increase 
 in population during the last one hundred and fifty years, the mar- 
 ginal productivity of labor would (if, nevertheless, modern methods 
 of production had been developed) have been very much higher 
 than it is, and wages would have been correspondingly higher 
 than they are. 
 
 The Subsistence Theory of Wages. The doctrine that wages 
 tend, in the long run, to equal a bare subsistence, was a theory 
 advanced by English economists in the first quarter of the nine- 
 teenth century as a corollary of the Malthusian law of population. 
 Said Ricardo: "The natural price of labor is that price which is 
 necessary to enable the laborers, one with another, to subsist and 
 to perpetuate their race, without either increase or diminution." 
 Granting the premises, the logic was incontrovertible: If wages 
 
 1 This figure was applied to the effect of an increase in wealth upon the growth of 
 the population by Sir James Steuart, in his treatise on Political Economy (1767).
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 377 
 
 fall below this level of subsistence, the result will be, in the long run, 
 fewer laborers and therefore higher wages. If the increase in 
 wages goes beyond the level fixed by the cost of subsistence, the 
 result will be, according to the Malthusian doctrine, more laborers 
 and therefore lower wages. The cost of subsistence in this view 
 formed the " expenses of production " of labor, and the actual 
 wages determined by supply and demand were supposed to fluctu- 
 ate around these normal wages as the market values of commodi- 
 ties fluctuate around the normal values fixed by the expenses 
 of production. Socialists and advocates of the single tax have 
 made much of this theory of wages as proving the impossibility 
 of bettering the condition of the laboring class under existing 
 conditions. By some socialists this doctrine, in its most rigid 
 form, has been called the " iron law of wages." But socialists 
 and followers of Henry George alike have to face the difficulty 
 of accepting this theory and at the same time rejecting the theory 
 of population on which it rests a theory which they cannot 
 accept, for its truth would obviously place insuperable obstacles 
 in the way of any lasting improvement in wages being achieved 
 through the adoption of their schemes. The subsistence theory 
 of wages, if true, would hold just as true under socialism or under 
 the national ownership of land as under existing conditions. 
 
 It should be said that the subsistence theory of wages was in 
 part a reflex of the conditions actually existing in England at the 
 time. Wages were very low, and the law required that deficiencies 
 in wages, below the amount necessary for the maintenance of the 
 laborer and his family, should be made up out of parish funds 
 a provision which in itself tended to keep down wages, and was 
 made still worse by the fact that the allowance for maintenance 
 to each family was proportioned to the size of the family, thus 
 encouraging the rapid increase of the population. 
 
 The Relation of the Standard of Life to the Supply of Labor. 
 Whatever may have been the case in the past, the subsistence 
 theory of wages does not square with the facts of to-day, for the 
 amount paid in wages is obviously considerably more than is 
 " necessary to enable the laborers to subsist and to perpetuate 
 their race, without either increase or diminution." Ricardo him-
 
 378 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 self did not give to the " minimum of subsistence " the fixed and 
 rigid meaning which some socialists have attached to it. It 
 varied, he recognized, with the habits and customs of the people. 
 In this more elastic form the " minimum of subsistence " shades 
 into what is termed more accurately the " standard of life." The 
 number and character of the wants which a man considers more 
 important than marriage and family constitute his standard of life. 
 Whenever wages fall below a point where the standard of life can 
 be maintained for a family, the workman will do without the family 
 and maintain the standard of life for himself alone. While the 
 increase in the quantity of goods produced that has taken place by 
 reason of the industrial revolution and the utilization of new and 
 vast bodies of natural resources has been attended with an unprece- 
 dented increase in population, it has also been attended with an 
 improvement in the standard of living. Every advance in the 
 standard of life marks a step definitely gained in the economic 
 progress of the laboring class ; it affords a vantage ground for yet 
 farther progress. 
 
 This is not only because the standard of life is, by very definition, 
 a fundamental factor in determining, in the long run, the supply 
 of labor, but also because experience has shown that the standard 
 of life affords an element of strength to laborers in their bargains 
 with employers. Any encroachments on it are met with strong 
 and determined resistance. Moreover, a high standard of life is, 
 as we have seen, one of the things that make for productive effi- 
 ciency on the part of the laborer, and hence tend to increase his 
 earning capacity. Many persons who are deeply interested in 
 the welfare of the laboring class believe that the wisest philanthropy 
 is embodied in the efforts that are made to raise the level of living. 
 Among such efforts are included such things as the work of social 
 settlements, public and private movements to secure better con- 
 ditions of housing, municipal expenditures for places of public 
 recreation, for public libraries, for such things even as clean and 
 well-lighted streets; and, above all, public education. 
 
 The extent to which the possibility of attaining a still higher standard of 
 living operates as a restraining force upon the increase of the population is 
 largely determined by the extent to which democratic ideals are realized
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 379 
 
 in the social organization. It is a noticeable fact, for example, that the first 
 generation of immigrants to the United States bring with them the habits and 
 ways of living of their European homes. So long as simple standards of life 
 are retained in connection with the larger incomes which they are able to_ 
 earn in this country, more of them are able to marry ; they are able to marry 
 earlier, and they can raise larger families. But the second generation grows 
 up in an American environment. They attend our public schools, where they 
 mingle with American children and receive an American education. The 
 possibility of taking a social and economic position higher than that of their 
 parents is opened up to them. They become saturated with the American no- 
 tion that each man has a chance to climb to the top of the ladder. They find 
 here no rigid barriers separating social classes from one another. "Like 
 father, like son" may have been true in Europe ; here it has no binding force. 
 Hence the birth rate among our native population of foreign parentage is 
 very much lower than the birth rate among our foreign-born population. 
 
 The Supply of Labor in Different Occupations. Just as the 
 demand for labor on the part of entrepreneurs is not a demand for 
 " labor in general," but a demand for specific kinds of labor, 
 so the supply of labor is the supply of laborers who are able and 
 willing to do certain definite kinds of work. The supply of labor 
 in any given occupation is, at any given time, almost as rigidly 
 fixed as is the supply of labor in general. Laborers can usually 
 change from one occupation to another only at the loss of the 
 advantage of whatever specialized skill they may have acquired. 
 This is, however, a matter of occupation, not of industries. There 
 is, for example, a wide range of industries open to a skilled me- 
 chanic or a stationary engineer. In the skilled trades what varia- 
 bility there is in the supply (at any given time) comes less from 
 any possibility of passing from one trade to another than from the 
 opportunities the more efficient and ambitious workmen have of 
 entering business on their own account (that is, of becoming entre- 
 preneurs) or of entering some calling where ability, rather than 
 specialized skill, is the prime requisite. The carpenter may be- 
 come a contractor; the skilled mechanic may become a traveling 
 salesman, and this, very likely, in some line where his specialized 
 skill will still be of some advantage. The options thus open to 
 the stronger members of each group should not be lost sight of 
 in any consideration of the forces tending to resist a downward 
 movement in the wages paid in any occupation.
 
 380 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Throughout the greater part of American history the most im- 
 portant option of this kind has been due to the existence of a large 
 body of free land. The mobility of labor in this country has been 
 such that it has been impossible for wages to fall much below 
 the amount which a man could make for himself by taking up 
 government land on the frontier. To-day, however, we are con- 
 fronted by a different set of conditions. The frontier has com- 
 pleted its journey across the continent, and there remains for the 
 settler only such land as irrigation may reclaim from the arid 
 regions of the West. The wage earner will henceforth be without 
 the strong support of the economic alternative of a living got 
 from free land. 
 
 When we take the long-period point of view, we find more elas- 
 ticity in the supply of labor in particular occupations. The ranks 
 of each trade are being continually depleted by old age, death, 
 and, to some extent, by the alternatives open to its stronger mem- 
 bers. These gaps need not be filled by an incoming body of ap- 
 prentices if the wages paid are lower than the wages in other 
 occupations demanding a similar degree of preparation and ability. 
 But there is a certain amount of inelasticity even here, for a variety 
 of reasons, among which we may note: the habit of imitation, 
 which leads a boy to enter the same occupation his acquaintances 
 have chosen; the not infrequent tendency of sons to enter their 
 father's occupation; lack of knowledge or of early appreciation 
 of the relative advantages of different employments, and the fact 
 that only a small number of options may be open to the residents 
 of a particular territory. These facts, in turn, have an important 
 bearing upon the localization of industry, for industries are apt 
 to be located in places where there is a present and prospective 
 supply of specially skilled labor. 
 
 Differences in wages, together with other factors just mentioned, 
 are not, however, the only considerations which attract laborers 
 to different occupations. Many economic writers have observed 
 that there are differences in the wages paid in different employ- 
 ments which are out of all proportion to any differences in the 
 training or the ability they require. Adam Smith enumerated 
 five circumstances which " make up for a small pecuniary gain in
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 381 
 
 some employments, and counterbalance a great one in others." 
 These are: "I. The agreeableness or disagreeableness of the 
 employments themselves; II. The easiness and cheapness, or 
 the difficulty and expense, of learning them; III. The constancy 
 or inconstancy of employment in them; IV. The small or great 
 trust which must be reposed in those who exercise them ; and V. 
 The probability or improbability of success in them." These cir- 
 cumstances need explanation in two particulars: First, the agree- 
 ableness or disagreeableness of an employment is very often a 
 matter of the social standing attached to it. Many men are doing 
 clerical work to whom some kind of physical exertion would be 
 both more pleasant and more profitable, but who dislike to be 
 classed among the " manual laborers." So-called " professional 
 pursuits " attract many men to whom more lucrative opportunities, 
 requiring less special preparation, are open in other employments. 
 In the second place, the significance of these circumstances is 
 affected by the fact that the most poorly paid (because the least 
 efficient) laborers are found in the most disagreeable and the most 
 uncertain employments. 
 
 The Wage Contract. The wages that a laborer actually 
 receives are determined by an agreement between himself and his 
 employer. Here appear again those " gains of bargaining " 
 which were mentioned in the discussion of the prices of commodi- 
 ties. But in the case of the wage agreement, if the bargain is 
 between an employer and an individual workman, the advantage 
 is apt to be all on one side. The employer is apt to know pretty 
 accurately what he can afford to pay the laborer; he knows about 
 how much the laborer will add to his product, and his knowledge 
 of business conditions helps him to estimate the value of this added 
 product. He knows what it would cost him to get his added prod- 
 uct in other ways, as by paying some of his present employees 
 for " overtime " work, or possibly by speeding his machinery 
 faster. Moreover, there is the possibility, or even probability, of 
 getting some other laborer, in case he fails to come to an agree- 
 ment with the one in question. His experience as an employer 
 of laborers will help him to gage the minimum that the laborer 
 will accept. With the laborer the situation is very different. He
 
 382 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 can gage with less accuracy just how much his services are worth 
 to the employer. The minimum wage that he will accept will be 
 governed by his very limited power of holding out for higher wages, 
 or by his estimate of what he can get in other employments 
 very few of which may be open to him. The whole situation may 
 be expressed by the statement that it is usually a matter of small 
 importance to the employer whether or not he secures a particular 
 laborer, while the securing of a particular employment is often 
 a matter of the very greatest importance to the laborer. Under 
 these conditions wages are apt to be fixed much closer to the 
 minimum which the laborer will take than to the ma'ximum which 
 the employer will pay. Where laborers can bargain in groups 
 rather than as individuals, their disadvantages are greatly lessened. 
 The fundamental motive underlying the organization of labor 
 unions has been to secure the advantages of collective bargaining. 
 
 Wages and Efficiency. That wages vary with the efficiency of individual 
 laborers is a fact of common observation. Wages are paid for the products 
 of individual laborers (or, under collective bargaining, for the products of 
 groups of laborers), and the amount of a laborer's product obviously depends 
 very largely upon his efficiency. Some writers have even gone so far as to 
 speak of "no-rent" laborers, the least efficient ones, and to press the 
 analogy between the differential gain which the more efficient laborers get 
 and the rent of land. This procedure is, however, more confusing than useful 
 in the explanation of wages. So far as the distribution of laborers according 
 to their efficiency is concerned, there seems to be a common impression to the 
 effect that it is of a kind that could be represented graphically by a pyramid, 
 the least efficient and relatively most numerous classes forming the base of 
 the pyramid, and the numbers growing constantly smaller and smaller 
 as the scale of efficiency ascends. Now unless we beg the whole question 
 of the relation of wages to efficiency by assuming that efficiency is measured 
 by the ability to get high wages, we will find it very difficult to get a definite 
 statistical test of the distribution of efficiency among men. For when we 
 speak of efficiency, we usually mean either efficiency for a particular purpose, 
 or a combination of physical, mental, and moral qualities, " general sagacity 
 and energy, " as Professor Marshall has put it. There is, however, one 
 ascertained fact of great significance, and that is that the distribution of such 
 physical and mental characteristics of men as have been measured and tabu- 
 lated in statistical form seem to conform more or less closely to what is known 
 as the "normal law of error," * or the "normal frequency curve." 
 
 1 So named because it expresses the accuracy of such things as a large number 
 of shots at a target, or a large number of astronomical observations on the position 
 of a fixed star.
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 
 
 383 
 
 Assume, for illustration, that we are dealing with the measurements of 
 the stature of a large number of men. Let all the different degrees of 
 stature be represented by successive points on the line AAz, (Fig. i). so 
 
 Q P S. 
 
 FIG. i 
 
 that the least height will be at A and the greatest at AI. Then let vertical 
 distances measured upward from these points represent the relative number 
 of men found to be of each of these different degrees of stature. Thus the 
 relative number of men of height P is represented by the length of the line 
 PG, while the line QH represents the relative number of men of stature Q. 
 The curve AA\A%, which connects the tops of all these imaginary vertical 
 lines, represents the distribution according to stature of all the men meas- 
 ured. Two important characteristics of this curve will be noted: first, the 
 most commonly found stature is the medium or average stature, while ex- 
 tremely tall or extremely short men are the least frequent ; second, the curve 
 is symmetrical ; that is, as many men are found to be 20 per cent shorter 
 than the average as are found to be 20 per cent taller than the average. 
 The curve BB\B% is precisely the same sort of curve, and it represents the 
 measurements of just as many men (for its area is the same as that of the 
 curve AA\A%), but it is constructed on the assumption that stature is only 
 half as variable as is assumed in the curve AA\A%. This assumption would 
 mean that men were, with respect to stature, concentrated more closely 
 around the average than is indicated by the first curve. Not only with 
 respect to physical measurements of various kinds (such as of cranial capac- 
 ity, or of the ratio of length of the head to its breadth), but also with respect 
 to measurements of many specific kinds of mental efficiency ' men are found 
 to be distributed with " normal frequency." It follows that the most prob- 
 able kind of distribution of men with respect to the complex of physical, 
 mental, and moral qualities, included under the general term "efficiency," 
 is something closely approximating this normal type. If the curve 
 
 1 Cf. E. L. Thorndike, Mental and Social Measurements, especially page 59.
 
 384 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 represents the distribution of men according to their efficiency, we may 
 assume that those represented by the part of the area to the left of a certain 
 line (HQ, for example) are those who are below the level of social utiliza- 
 tion, including the physically and mentally defective and the morally delin- 
 quent classes. Similarly, those represented by the area to the right of the 
 line IR would include the most efficient members of the population, the 
 individuals of exceptional ability. When one speaks of " commonplace 
 mediocrity " he has in mind its relatively greater frequency. 
 
 Figure 2 is based upon a table which shows the weekly wages received 
 in 1900 by 160,000 employees in 30 industries, including textile mills, wood 
 
 22 
 20 
 18 
 16 
 
 E" 
 
 012 
 
 10 
 
 8 
 C 
 4 
 I 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 FT 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 J 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 C 
 L 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 < 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 246 
 
 S 10 12 14 1C 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 12 11 16 18 W 
 WEEKLY WAE8 IN DOLORS 
 
 FIG. 2 
 
 working, metal working, and miscellaneous industries. 1 In this diagram 
 the horizontal line represents the various weekly wages received (greater 
 than two dollars and less than fifty dollars a week) classified in two-dollar 
 groups. The vertical distances represent in each case the proportion 
 of the total number of employees who received the wage specified. Thus 
 the diagram shows that over 23 per cent of the employees were paid 
 between eight and ten dollars a week, and that over 5 per cent received 
 between eighteen and twenty dollars per week. If wages varied exactly 
 according to efficiency, we would expect that this diagram would follow the 
 general pattern of the normal frequency curve shown in Figure i. There 
 are, however, some noticeable differences. The median wage (the wage 
 which divides the whole number of employees into two halves, one half 
 receiving more and one half receiving less than the median wage), which is 
 in this case about $10.50, was not located at the point of greatest frequency, 
 
 1 The statistics were gathered by the United States Census Office and printed 
 in the special report of the Twelfth Census on Employees and Wages. The 
 tabulation on which the diagram is based is taken from an article on "The 
 Variability of Wages," by Professor H. L. Moore, in the Political Science Quar- 
 terly, Vol. XXII, p. 67. See also an article by Professor Moore on "The 
 Efficiency Theory of Wages," Economic Journal, Vol. XVII, p. 571.
 
 THE WAGES OF LABOR 385 
 
 as is true of the normal frequency curve, but somewhat above it. The 
 average wages (the quotient obtained by dividing the total amount paid in 
 wages by the number of employees) was still higher, amounting to about 
 $11.50. The diagram is not symmetrical, but shows a concentration of 
 employees in the lower wage groups, and a relatively greater variation or 
 " dispersion " in the case of those receiving higher wages. This suggests 
 that either differences in wages are not so great in the lower wage groups 
 as differences in efficiency, or that differences in wages in the higher wage 
 groups are greater than differences in efficiency. In general, differences in 
 wages seem to increase more rapidly than differences in efficiency as the 
 scale of efficiency ascends. If wages are paid for the productivity of the 
 individual workman, and if productivity varies with efficiency, what is 
 the explanation of this difference between the distribution of efficiency and 
 the distribution of wages? 
 
 First, it should be noted that the normal frequency curve only applies 
 to so-called "natural" efficiency, made up of inherited qualities. Actual 
 productive efficiency is a product not only of natural efficiency, but also of 
 training, and this acquired element of specialized skill is more important in 
 the case of the better workmen than in the case of the less efficient. In the 
 second place, higher-paid workmen are in better-organized trades, and gain 
 more than do the others from the advantages of collective bargaining. In the 
 third place, when we speak of the productivity of a laborer as a fundamental 
 thing determining his wages, we have in mind the amount of product imputed 
 to the laborer the amount by which the total product would be decreased 
 if his labor were not utilized. This amount depends not only upon the 
 efficiency, natural and acquired, of the laborer, but also (on account of the 
 law of diminishing productivity) upon the extent to which the employer 
 finds it profitable to utilize labor rather than capital or land. This, on 
 account of the fact that the sale of labor is analogous to a "forced sale," is 
 apt to be determined largely by the supply of labor in each employment. 
 So far as the supply of labor in the better-paid trades is restricted through the 
 limitation of apprenticeship, or through other means, the marginal produc- 
 tivity of labor in other employments is (since the restriction of the supply of 
 labor in any one employment necessitates a corresponding increase of the 
 supply in some other employments) relatively decreased. These three con- 
 siderations account, at least partially, for the difference between the dis- 
 tribution of wages and the probable distribution of natural efficiency. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 i. How far are wages determined by the productivity of labor ? In what 
 different ways do wages affect the productivity of labor? What meaning, 
 or meanings, do you attach to the word " productivity " in the foregoing 
 
 questions ?
 
 386 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 2. Why are the wages of men higher than the wages of women in the same 
 employments ? 
 
 3. Make a short outline, or table, of the factors determining the supply 
 and demand of labor. 
 
 4. Are wages paid as a reward for the irksomeness of labor? Are they 
 paid on account of the scarcity of labor? 
 
 5. Some economists have held that "a demand for commodities is not a 
 demand for labor." Discuss this statement. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. IV. 
 
 CLARK, J. B. The Distribution of Wealth, Chaps. VII and VIII. 
 
 DAVIDSON, JOHN. The Bargain Theory of Wages. 
 
 FETTER, F. A. Principles of Economics, Chaps. XX-XXVI. 
 
 FLUX, A. W. Economic Principles, Chap. VIII. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED, Principles of Economics, 4th. ed., Book VI, Chaps. I-V. 
 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Wages and Capital. 
 
 THOMPSON, H. M. The Theory of Wages.
 
 CHAPTER XXIII 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 
 
 WHATEVER maybe the economic law in accordance with which 
 wages are fixed, it must be vitalized or expressed by the conscious 
 efforts of human agents. For instance, it is frequently said that 
 the price of labor is determined by the law of demand and supply. 
 This may be true, but the law of demand and supply is animated 
 by no mystical or occult force; it must be enforced by active, in- 
 telligent men, keen enough to know their own interest, and bent 
 upon pursuing it. Men must take advantage of the economic 
 forces working to their advantage, or they will lose their advantage. 
 
 Types of Labor Organizations. One of the most important 
 agents now occupied in giving effect to the economic laws which 
 control wages is the labor organization. There are at least three 
 distinct types of labor organizations : the Trade Union, represent- 
 ing a combination of wage earners in a single trade or two or 
 three closely related trades; the Industrial Union, composed of 
 all kinds of wage earners working in a given industry; and the 
 mixed Labor Union, made up of wage earners from many trades 
 and many industries. Thus, the Brotherhood of Locomotive En- 
 gineers, a strict trades union, makes no attempt to include other 
 workers in the railway service; the United Mine Workers, how- 
 ever, an industrial union, attempts to combine all persons work- 
 ing in and around the mines; while the Knights of Labor, in the 
 period of its strength and prosperity, fused all sorts and condi- 
 tions of workers in some of its district assemblies, and combined 
 these assemblies in a closely knit, highly centralized national 
 organization. 
 
 The difference in the structure of labor organizations colors their 
 policies and gives rise to important problems. The trade and in- 
 
 387
 
 388 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 dustrial unions are, as we should expect, much more homogeneous 
 and therefore much more efficient than the labor unions, but they 
 are likely to be narrower in their aims and more selfish in their 
 policies. The labor unions, on the other hand, have in the past 
 proved much less efficient, much more unwieldy, and much more 
 disposed to make use of cooperation, political action, and other 
 devices which are not suited to associations of wage earners, or at 
 least not easily handled by them. 
 
 The most important problem growing out of the structure of 
 labor organizations is known as the jurisdiction dispute. Thus 
 the Knights of Labor, having received into their membership a 
 large number of cigar makers, fell into a sharp dispute with the 
 regular International Cigar Makers' Union, whose cause was natu- 
 rally espoused by the American Federation of Labor. In more 
 recent years bitter quarrels have taken place between the trade 
 and industrial unions. The United Brewery Workers, for in- 
 stance, an industrial union, has been quarreling for years with the 
 trade organizations among the painters, the coopers, and the sta- 
 tionary firemen. The American Federation of Labor, to which 
 most of these organizations belong, has usually favored the trades 
 unions in these disputes, and has recently ordered all coopers, 
 painters, and teamsters in the Brewery Workers' Union to join 
 the trades unions in their respective crafts. 
 
 For the larger and more general objects common to wage 
 workers as a body, many of the American unions have combined 
 in a large, loosely knit confederacy, known as the American Fed- 
 eration of Labor. This organization interferes just as little as 
 possible with the constituent unions, and confines its activity to 
 securing favorable labor laws, organizing trades in districts of the 
 country in which trades unions have heretofore failed to get a start, 
 rendering assistance to unions which are hard pushed in strikes or 
 other disputes with employers, encouraging the use of union-label 
 goods, and, in short, to furthering all those interests which labor 
 organizations have in common. In recent years the American 
 Federation of Labor has grown with extraordinary rapidity. The 
 present (1908) membership is about 2,000,000. 
 
 The Economic Justification of Labor Organizations. The
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 389 
 
 question is often asked why labor organizations are neces- 
 sary, in view of the fact that wages are fixed, at least within broad 
 limits, by deep-lying economic and social forces which the labor 
 organization cannot effectively control. If wages depend upon 
 demand and supply, it is said, what excuse for the troublesome 
 and irritating trades union ? 
 
 The answer has been partially stated above. Economic laws 
 work themselves out through men and through organizations 
 they are not self-enforcing. We have had labor organizations of 
 one kind and another ever since the wage system existed, and we 
 shall unquestionably continue to have such organizations until the 
 wage system is superseded by something more satisfactory. 
 
 There are, however, additional reasons for the existence of the 
 labor organization. Wages, we say, are measured by the mar- 
 ginal productivity of labor. This productivity, in turn, is partially 
 dependent upon the demand and supply of labor. But the sup- 
 ply of labor is largely controlled, as we have seen, by the standard 
 of life; and one of the great functions of the labor organizations is 
 to strengthen and advance the standard of life. If a great horde 
 of unorganized and unsympathetic wage earners are continually 
 bidding against one another in the labor market, each individual 
 endeavoring to get a little more work by offering to take a little 
 less pay, the standard of living will be subtly undermined, "nib- 
 bled away," as a well-known writer has expressed it. The labor 
 organization, by repressing the vicious activity of this competition, 
 by compelling its members to offer the same terms and abide by 
 common or standard rules, bulwarks the standard of life, and gives 
 it increased precision, increased power and durability. In addi- 
 tion, most unions endeavor to exercise a more direct and positive 
 influence upon the supply of labor, by limiting the number of 
 apprentices, helpers, and other persons entering the trade. These 
 efforts, however, are not always successful. 
 
 Current economic doctrine recognizes at least one other legiti- 
 mate function of the labor organization. In actual life there is 
 always a margin between the actual productivity of the wage 
 earner and the amount which he receives as wages. The em- 
 ployer cannot pay the worker all the latter makes; if he did, he
 
 390 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 would have no profits. By stout resistance and skillful bargain- 
 ing it is possible for the wage worker to get a part of that share of 
 the product which in the past has gone to the employer as profits. 
 Of course, that labor organization will be most successful in the 
 long run which increases the productivity of its members, and 
 thus creates a larger product to be distributed among all the fac- 
 tors of production. But even if the organization does not increase 
 the productivity of its members, it has a chance to improve their 
 wages by trenching upon profits. Mere bargaining, therefore, de- 
 spite the operation of more fundamental economic forces, is still 
 exceedingly important. And the unorganized wage worker, being 
 a poor bargainer, combines with his fellow- workmen, not only to 
 maintain a more uniform price for their labor, but in order to 
 procure the guidance and assistance of an expert bargainer the 
 business agent or walking delegate. The labor organization is 
 thus a commerical institution for the sale of labor in large quan- 
 tities; its primary function is collective bargaining. 
 
 Labor Organizations and Monopoly. It is plain that the labor 
 organization as a wholesale jobber of labor is essentially a prod- 
 uct of those familiar economic forces making for large-scale com- 
 mercial dealings; it is brother to the trust, akin to the combination, 
 and thus not untainted with monopoly. One of the most searching 
 criticisms directed against the labor organization is that it exhibits 
 all the evil tendencies of monopoly. The charge has some ele- 
 ments of truth. The highest aim of the average labor organiza- 
 tion is to induce every worker in the industry to join the union, 
 so that by monopolizing the supply of labor it may control the 
 price. But in its principal implications the charge of monopoly 
 is misleading, because the great majority of unions do not attempt 
 to limit the number of their beneficiaries. They aim to increase 
 wages, but they are willing and even anxious that every member 
 of the craft should share the increase. It is rare for a labor or- 
 ganization to exclude from its ranks a number of workers and 
 then persecute them by refusing to work with them or treating 
 them as scabs. Conflicts with non-union men are common, but 
 in a very large majority of cases every effort has been made to get 
 these men into the union. An organization which is constantly
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 391 
 
 exhorting its competitors to come into the combination and share 
 its benefits cannot logically be called a monopoly. 
 
 Methods and Policies of Labor Organizations. The aims of 
 labor organizations and the policies employed to achieve their 
 ends vary in accordance with the conditions of the occupation or 
 industry in which their members work. Some unions, for in- 
 stance, lay great emphasis upon apprenticeship; and if they thus 
 secure control of the supply of labor in the trade, find it necessary 
 to place but little dependence upon strikes and boycotts. On the 
 other hand, organizations like the Brotherhood of Locomotive 
 Engineers find this question settled for them; no one can perform 
 the work of a locomotive engineer without preliminary training, 
 and this natural limitation of the number of trained locomotive 
 engineers makes it possible for their union to get along without 
 maintaining either apprenticeship regulations or the policy of the 
 closed shop. And for years it has not indulged in a strike. An 
 admirable system of mutual insurance and simple collective bar- 
 gaining are sufficient to keep the membership loyal and obtain 
 from employers fair rates of pay. 
 
 In the unskilled trades, on the other hand, where a period of 
 apprenticeship is wholly superfluous, some more artificial protec- 
 tion of the standard of life must be employed, like the "policy of 
 the closed shop"; * and this naturally forces the union, in turn, to 
 place great dependence upon the strike and boycott. Before con- 
 demning a union for employing some of these policies, therefore, 
 or contrasting it unfavorably with highly conservative unions, like 
 the Railway Brotherhoods, it is necessary to inquire whether or 
 not, like the Railway Brotherhoods, it is protected by some natu- 
 ral condition of the business, which makes peaceable collective 
 bargaining comparatively easy. 
 
 It is impossible to pass any general verdict upon the justice of 
 the closed-shop policy. Most Americans are inclined to condemn 
 
 1 The familiar union rule prohibiting members of the union from working with 
 non-union men. The policy is very elastic. No objection is made to working with 
 members of an occupation not yet organized; some unions apply the ban only to 
 non-union men in the same trade or craft ; while others practically refuse to work 
 for an employer who hires any non-union men at all (not applying the term 
 "non-union men" to laborers, porters, and other unorganized workers).
 
 392 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 it offhand as an attempt to deprive the non-union man of his 
 "sacred right to work." They forget that the union man en- 
 forces the closed-shop policy by an exercise of his "sacred right 
 of quitting work." Except where violence is employed, the union 
 which is attempting to enforce a closed-shop policy threatens to 
 do nothing worse than direct its members to quit the employment 
 of the proprietor of the open shop in question. Two equally 
 "sacred and inalienable rights" clash in this contest, and it is 
 plain that no decision concerning the legitimacy of the closed-shop 
 policy can be determined by reference to a philosophy of rights. 
 If we would know whether a strike against non-union men is jus- 
 tifiable or unjustifiable, we must inquire into all the surrounding 
 circumstances and the manner in which the strike is conducted. 
 If the strike is conducted peaceably, and if the union in question 
 is an open union, cordially inviting the "scabs" to enter and 
 share its benefits; if the rate of wages and other conditions of 
 employment demanded by the union men are reasonable in view 
 of the cost of living and other similar conditions; if the "scabs" 
 involved, by accepting less than a living wage or other harmful 
 conditions of employment, are working even though of necessity 
 to undermine the American standard of living; then we have 
 no hesitation in saying that the employment of the closed-shop 
 policy on the part of the union is thoroughly justifiable. 
 
 We are much too prone in a case like this to see only the injury 
 done to the non-union man, forgetful of the fact that the non- 
 union man does a real injury to his fellow- workers by accepting 
 wages or other conditions of employment that are inconsistent 
 with the American mode of living. The price cutter in the labor 
 market is not ordinarily a social benefactor. The weakest, dull- 
 est, and least enterprising laborer exerts an influence upon the 
 general level of wages out of all proportion to his importance or 
 his deserts. If this be true, the man who cuts the standard rate 
 of wages may do a grave social injury, and there is justification for 
 those who peaceably combine to prevent him from doing his de- 
 structive work. It must be remembered, however, that these con- 
 clusions are based upon the assumption that the union is an open 
 union and that the strike is conducted without intimidation or
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 393 
 
 interference with the non-union men. The moment the union 
 stoops to violence, that moment it loses all claim to the support of 
 an enlightened public opinion. 
 
 Another policy which is generally, and in many cases unjustly, 
 condemned is the regulation of output, systematically practiced 
 and indorsed by most unions. The output of the worker is lim- 
 ited in many ways. The reduction of the hours of labor, the limi- 
 tation of wages which some unions working by the piece system 
 enforce, the prohibition or penalization of overtime, all operate 
 to check the activity or reduce the output of the particular work- 
 man. Here, again, it is unsafe to render any general verdict upon 
 the legitimacy of the policy in question. In some industries in 
 which the piece system is employed, the rate per piece has unques- 
 tionably been forced down and the workers spurred to excessive 
 exertion by the pressure and influence of pace makers or task 
 masters, paid by the employers to urge the workers to the utmost 
 speed. Where such conditions prevail, no one can successfully 
 question the justice of the feeling which leads the union to object 
 to the presence of pace makers and to prescribe a maximum wage 
 usually above that secured by the average workman which 
 union members are not permitted to exceed. In general, it is plain 
 that an individual laborer may underbid a competitor by working 
 more intensely, as well as by offering to work longer hours or at 
 lower pay. On this account alone, trades unions are justified in 
 defining and maintaining some regular pace or standard intensity 
 of work. Without such definition, collective bargaining would be 
 impossible. This last observation, it will be noted, applies only 
 to trades working by the day. But even where the piece system 
 is used, the workers may be justified in fixing a liberal limit to the 
 amount of piecework which the wage earner shall be permitted to 
 do in a day. For there can be no question that unregulated piece- 
 work does stimulate the worker to excessive exertion, and that as 
 daily earnings under the piece system tend to rise, the employer 
 is tempted to reduce the rates. 
 
 Some methods of restriction, however, are wholly vicious. The 
 Journeyman Stone Cutters' Union, for instance, stoutly resisted 
 for years the application of machinery to their work, and actually
 
 394 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 attempted to prevent the shipment of machine-planed stone into 
 any city where the union had succeeded in preventing the intro- 
 duction of planers. Such an attitude toward the introduction of 
 labor-saving devices deserves the severest condemnation. More- 
 over, in some unions there is a tacit approval of the " go-easy " 
 system, the system of " soldiering," or " adulterating labor," as it 
 has been aptly termed. Such a method of restricting output not 
 only corrupts the character of the individual workman who prac 
 tices it, but makes it impossible for the employer- to deal with the 
 union as a seller of honest goods, and in this way tends to under- 
 mine the whole foundation of trades unionism, which is, as has 
 been said, collective bargaining. On the other hand, there is no 
 particular reason to believe that union labor is especially open to 
 the charge of encouraging " go-easy " habits of work. The habit 
 of stealthy loafing is found at its worst in certain occupations in 
 which labor organizations are unknown, so that when it appears 
 among union workmen it cannot logically be attributed to organi- 
 zation alone. 
 
 Educational and Fraternal Activities. Practically all unions 
 have important educational and social activities. Debate upon 
 economic topics is common in union meetings, particularly at the 
 conventions of the state and national organizations. It has even 
 been said that foreign-born wage earners receive their most help- 
 ful and vital education in American public questions through the 
 agency of the union. This broad education, which is a most im- 
 portant factor in elevating the standard of life, is supplemented by 
 the social activities of the labor organization. Many unions main- 
 tain a so-called " Ladies' Auxiliary," in which the wives of the 
 members participate ; give concerts, dances, and other social en- 
 tertainments, maintain charitable activities, and by general social 
 intercourse operate to unify and solidify the standard of life of 
 the wage-earning group concerned. 
 
 Closely allied with these educational and social features is the 
 system of insurance benefits, which has played such a prominent 
 part in the development of labor organizations. In Great Britain 
 fully three times as much money is expended by the unions upon 
 mutual insurance of various kinds as upon administrative activi-
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 395 
 
 ties, or for the support and encouragement of strikes. In the 
 year 1901, for instance, eighty-nine of the one hundred most 
 prominent British unions paid funeral benefits, eighty-three strike 
 benefits, seventy-seven unemployed benefits, seventy-seven sick 
 or accident benefits, and thirty-eight superannuation benefits. 
 Union insurance is exceedingly helpful, not only in stimulating 
 thrift among the individual members, but in making the union 
 more careful and conservative in its policies. Moreover, it 
 serves to keep in the union a large number of members, who, 
 if they had no financial stake in continued membership, would 
 drop out of the union in times of peace, when no apparent 
 advantage was to be derived from the union. All things consid- 
 ered, the Cigars Makers' International Union has many claims to 
 be considered the most successful American labor organization ; 
 and its success is in large degree, if not in the largest degree, attribu- 
 table to its wise and extensive use of mutual insurance. But on 
 the whole, the American unions make relatively little use of the 
 insurance benefit. Most of them pay strike benefits, that is part 
 of their fighting policy, and perhaps a majority of them pay 
 funeral benefits, while a respectable majority pay sick benefits. 
 But the employment of the superannuation, accident, traveling, or 
 " out-of-work " benefit is comparatively rare. The great majority 
 of American unions are militant in character, existing primarily 
 for the purpose of collective bargaining, and placing the greatest 
 reliance upon the policy of the closed shop and the strike. 
 
 The Strike. : Probably the most important weapon of the trades 
 union is the strike. Unfortunately, also, the weapon is far too 
 frequently used. Several generations ago most trades unions, while 
 they vehemently defended their right to strike, cordially indorsed 
 arbitration and apparently looked upon the strike as a weapon of 
 last resort. To-day, the average trades union is at best only a 
 lukewarm advocate of arbitration, while it has come to regard 
 striking as a permanent policy. The net result has been to com- 
 mercialize the strike, as it were. Instead of being a more or less 
 spontaneous outburst against conditions which the workingman 
 regarded as unrighteous and oppressive, the strike has come to be 
 a commonplace method of bettering conditions of employment ;
 
 396 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 a device to be employed when conditions are favorable, to be laid 
 aside when conditions are unfavorable, but to be used without 
 regard to ethical consideration when its use appears to be profit- 
 able. As a result in this change in policy, strikes appear to be 
 increasing steadily in the United States, as may be seen in the 
 statistics quoted on the following pages. 
 
 While these statistics fluctuate in a very irregular way, there can be no 
 doubt that they show a decided increase in the number of strikes, strikers, 
 and employees thrown out of work by strikes. Moreover, comparison of the 
 number of employees thrown out of work with the general wage-earning 
 population indicates, although not so certainly, that the proportion of work- 
 ingmen annually involved in strikes has been slowly increasing in the twenty- 
 five years covered by the table. Precisely what is responsible for this 
 increase in strikes is difficult to determine. The change in the attitude of 
 labor organizations toward the strike is an important factor, no doubt. 
 But the greatest reason for the increase, in all probability, is the rapid growth 
 of organized labor. New unions are prone to strike. The sudden realiza- 
 tion of their new power, and the accumulation of strike funds, tempt them to 
 try their wings. In the long run organization probably exerts a conservative 
 and steadying influence: national machinery is created which curbs the 
 capricious impulses of the local unions ; experienced men are usually elected 
 to the more important national offices, and when they are called in to settle 
 a local grievance, they arrive upon the scene of action without personal re- 
 sentment against the employers involved. These facts create a strong hope, 
 and, indeed, a confident belief, among many of those who have studied the 
 labor question, that when practically all American trades are organized, 
 strikes will steadily decrease as they have in England, where a much larger 
 part of the wage-earning population is organized than in this country. 
 
 Labor leaders maintain that strikes strengthen the solidarity of 
 the unions, and encourage the members to make personal sacri- 
 fices for the common good, while they force employers to respect 
 the strength of organized labor, and are not, in the long run, par- 
 ticularly costly. The time lost in strikes, they say, merely takes 
 the place of enforced vacations, seasonal stoppages, and other kinds 
 of unemployment with which the average wage earner is nor- 
 mally visited during the course of the year's work. No amount 
 of such dialectic, however, can argue out of existence the injury 
 and destruction resulting from strikes. Many strikes are gravely 
 injurious to the wage earners themselves ; and almost all strikes 
 injure employers and the consuming public. From the social
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 
 
 397 
 
 a < 
 
 H e 
 
 iH 
 ^ > 
 
 . 2 
 
 o "8 u ^ 
 
 ^S^'S.K^SS M-cS^^^^ 
 
 Is* 
 
 Z H 
 
 - - f. 
 
 1~I 
 
 ^^R^S S.^5 ^t^^S>^ 
 
 U 3 
 
 i S 
 
 
 2* i 
 
 "8 
 
 rOM^O w O 'too OOO 'tOM 
 
 ft, a 
 
 ffj 
 
 cOM"5-5T V ^-? < ?5?;^S^ro 
 
 in 1 
 
 fc 3 
 
 
 H CO w o\ ^ M *"- *^> w ^- O CO O 
 
 K H 
 
 H a w 
 
 2; h 9 3 
 
 131 
 
 O Ji 
 
 cO fO 10 ^ I s * WNOO\OQOQW 
 
 CCMMCIMMMC4 M 
 
 U Q 
 
 S > 
 
 IN 
 
 oo w t^ M oo oo w ^ t 1 ** 10 o w o^ 
 
 *" 1 
 
 o 2 
 
 ill 
 
 O M 
 
 ^^^^^^^cS-^a^oc^ 
 
 z 
 
 | 
 
 vS 5 pt 5 vS R vS" sr 8, v8 % 8^ 
 
 H 
 MI W 
 
 1 
 
 MOO iriTtr^vO t^-Pi 'ti^.POMOO 
 
 s i s 
 
 
 
 N W 
 
 S 3 c/3 
 
 i"2- 
 
 8 ^ 8 s S, (X s 2 s 3- o S ^ R 
 
 ^5 
 
 H 
 
 t""* CO *O co O 1 * CO t^* ^) CO O CO 00 O 
 
 M M HI M HI 
 
 1 
 
 i! 
 
 S 8 JT g, eg S, v? 3 ?#$ J^S 
 
 
 CD u 
 
 S^^xo^^^^-xo^^S. 
 
 u 
 
 PQ H 
 X < X 
 
 O H W 
 
 r-00 to coofOP. 0*0 
 
 u; 
 
 5 w s 
 
 2 S 8,oJ?88^pT^^8 
 
 ^ 
 
 u 
 
 H 
 
 s ,. 
 
 K 
 
 &S- HJI-aSIg^o 
 
 1 
 
 3 
 
 8 
 
 2 5 ? pr^ S ? ? S^ s ^ 
 
 
 
 
 s-l S^^lrll III! 
 
 
 i 
 
 Si H-^^28?f^ 
 
 t 
 i 
 
 li 
 
 8 ^^^.t^^^S jf *!S 
 
 4 
 1 
 II 
 I 
 
 : M 
 
 I 
 
 M 
 
 
 i 
 3 
 
 J J1 $3 111 ? ElrS 
 
 
 =55 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 M pi PO t to *O f* 1 * OO O O M Pi **} 
 
 oooooocooooooooooo oooo 
 
 00000000000000000000000000 
 
 

 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 
 a 
 
 ^g 
 
 o'%>o 5 o 5 ooo P.^:?: 
 
 w 
 
 
 
 2 Pi 
 
 ^O* ^^'Sl'^-^ Jo ioNO o'vS 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 gl 
 
 Is. I 
 
 CO O oo ^ M oO O^ ^o f"* M vO ^ 
 
 VO 1 
 
 
 ** 
 
 111 
 
 ^-cocoS cT C "S N coc7'co C %^t 
 
 CO 
 
 
 fcS 
 
 o|l 
 
 8 ^^w-^^g^S ^^^ 
 
 IS 
 
 1 
 
 g g 
 
 H a ^ 
 g * 2 
 
 o "" S 
 
 H W OOO u^f^CCCO u^Tf^tt^- 
 
 M M M M 
 
 o 
 
 1 
 
 1 IT 
 
 <> 3 Q 
 
 By 
 
 w 2 * 
 
 9:*J 
 
 rLtoOoo^^cTo'o^"?^-? 
 
 CO 
 
 \ * 
 
 z 
 
 fc 2 N 
 
 111 
 
 o- 3, 
 
 S^^O^OOOO^^O 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 10 " 
 
 a fc 
 
 S5 
 
 | 
 
 M N ^ 1**. l-t M \S) O ^J" *O "**" OO 
 
 00 
 f- 
 
 w | 
 
 k. tn 
 
 & 
 
 ^cocow^fTw 1 c^cow'co? ^ 
 
 co 
 
 s 1 
 
 M S 
 
 g | g 
 
 lit 
 
 S.O^w^J?^ ^(^^-^ ^ 
 
 OO 
 
 .. 3 
 
 o S a 
 3 y 
 
 
 cpO^OOOJOt-.Mcojow 
 
 w 
 
 H 
 
 ^ 1 * 
 
 &| 
 
 ON ^* ON M w ^* *^ **** w *""" 00 ^* 
 
 Tj- 
 
 < 
 
 PH " 
 
 
 
 ^^^^^K^-^-^i-c^^- 
 
 
 
 K a 
 o * 
 
 W D 
 
 a f- 
 z < z 
 
 O H W 
 
 rt-ioO <txoe w f) Tfwu~w 
 
 ^ 
 
 w 1 
 
 
 
 ll 
 
 w 
 S " <* 
 
 g 3 
 
 ?o S N"N w^c^c^cCc^coc? 
 
 c? 
 
 D | 
 
 <a 
 
 g 
 
 H 
 
 S 
 
 H 
 
 S x 
 
 O a 
 
 z o 
 
 10 coowNNvOvON 10 w vO 
 w o t" O O r^* ^O CO O 10 w OO 
 
 w 
 
 00 
 
 G 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 fc 
 
 o 
 
 H 
 
 1 HtfSpllSs 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 OO" 
 
 K J 
 
 in s 
 
 
 H 
 
 f S=2 Stt^l ^i SS 
 
 00 
 
 
 W S 
 
 w fc 
 
 HH 
 
 S 
 
 
 H 
 
 t/5 
 
 &<%? %*, &>%%%%% 
 
 00 
 
 H 
 
 C/3 
 
 
 i. 
 
 ?Sil5'J1 < l'S & 
 
 o 
 
 
 1 
 
 I 1 
 
 OO*O *OOO ro - ON "^"O OOO 
 
 M M M C4 M 
 
 w 
 00 
 
 
 
 g 
 
 B 
 
 to w O O O *"** *"" ON w ^ *"O O 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 HMMMWWWNCOCONO) 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 i 
 
 Ttio>O r^oo OO w ci co-*io 
 ooooooo o o o o o 
 
 000000000000 OOOOOO 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 . 

 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 399 
 
 standpoint the strike is an evil, and all justifiable means should be 
 employed to prevent its occurrence. 
 
 We must not conclude, however, that workingmen and labor 
 organizations are wholly or even mainly responsible for strikes. 
 Indeed there are reasons to believe that the employers are more 
 often responsible for strikes than the employees. If a body of 
 men agree not to work for a given employer unless that employer 
 complies with certain conditions, whose fault is it if the employer 
 refuses to comply and a strike follows? Very evidently the fault 
 may lie with either the master or the men, or with both. The 
 fault lies with the men if the conditions which they demand are, 
 in view of all the circumstances, unreasonable and extortionate. 
 The fault lies with the employer if he refuses to grant reasonable 
 conditions of employment. Sometimes the fault is with one, some- 
 times with the other ; sometimes the one gains by the strike, some- 
 times the other; but the public, which is never at fault, stands 
 always to lose. The greatest lesson to be derived from a consid- 
 eration of strikes is the necessity of their suppression in the inter- 
 est of the general public. 
 
 One of the greatest evils attendant upon the strike is the violence 
 emanating from both sides from employers' associations as 
 well as from labor unions. It is frequently said that labor vio- 
 lence is diminishing with the passage of years. The statement is 
 both true and untrue. A close study of labor disputes in the early 
 period of the modern labor movement makes it very plain that 
 the average strike of that period was attended with much more 
 violence than the average strike of to-day. Most labor leaders 
 have thoroughly learned the lesson that violence does not pay, 
 and they exert every effort to suppress it. But at the same time 
 the average strike of the present time is attended with some vio- 
 lence or coercion, and the steady increase in the number of strikes 
 makes the aggregate volume of violence now greater than it was 
 in the past. 
 
 Historically, also, a marked change has shown itself in the char- 
 acter of the violence employed. In the past, labor lawlessness 
 was more or less sporadic; brutal, it is true, but frank and unpre- 
 meditated. The lawlessness of to-day, however, has taken on a
 
 400 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 far more sinister form ; it has become deliberate, premeditated, in 
 many cases official. No disinterested person can sift the testi- 
 mony in the labor troubles in the mining industry of Idaho and 
 Colorado without admitting that there has been a certain amount 
 of carefully planned violence perpetrated with the passive consent, 
 if not with the active encouragement, of union officials. There 
 can be no doubt, also, that individual employers and employer 
 associations have stooped to equally reprehensible practices. They 
 have employed as watchmen or detectives ex-convicts, thugs, arid 
 professional bad men, who unquestionably have not refrained at 
 times from perpetrating violence in order to cast discredit upon 
 the unions. It is impossible to say who began the trouble, and 
 just as impossible to conclude which side is the most to blame ; 
 the lesson to be drawn is the public necessity of suppressing and 
 punishing violence or intimidation, when practiced by either side 
 of the controversy. 
 
 Employers' Associations. The development of modern em- 
 ployers' associations has been briefly described in an earlier 
 chapter. Their activities give rise to a movement which may 
 be briefly described as an anti-labor movement. They are, in 
 almost every respect, the natural foil and counterpoise of the 
 labor organization. They resemble the association of laborers even 
 in structure. Thus we have employers' associations recruited en- 
 tirely from one industry, such as the Stove Founders' National 
 Defense Association ; associations of employers in distinct but 
 related industries, such as the national Metal Trade Association ; 
 and mixed associations in which all kinds of employers are united, 
 such as the Citizens' Alliances, so common now in many of the 
 Western cities. To complete the analogy, these associations are 
 combined in city, state, and national federations; thus forming 
 large confederacies, similar in scope and activity to the state and 
 national federation of labor. 
 
 We find the same resemblances between employers' associa- 
 tions and labor organizations when we examine the policies and 
 aims of the former. Thus they make frequent use of the lock- 
 out ; the Stove Founders' National Defense Association, for 
 example, began its interesting career with a lockout of the iron
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 40! 
 
 molders in the employ of its members. Like the trades unions, 
 also, they have their legislative committees or lobbies, and are 
 credited, for instance, with having played an important part 
 in defeating the eight-hour and anti-injunction bills which 
 have been before Congress several times. Some of these or- 
 ganizations also maintain so-called labor bureaus, whose func- 
 tion it is to secure accurate information of the workmen in 
 the trade, so that troublesome agitators may be refused em- 
 ployment ; and the methods employed in this branch of the 
 work gives rise to something closely akin to the "unfair list " pub- 
 lished by the American Federation of Labor and many national 
 unions. Some of the more radical associations have stooped at 
 times to violence and coercion, as was illustrated in 1904 by the 
 employers' associations of the Cripple Creek district which boy- 
 cotted business firms, forced public officials to resign by threats 
 or violence, and filled the vacant places with their own adherents. 
 Some of the employers' associations, like the Stove Founders' 
 National Defense Association, are conservative in tone and policy, 
 working harmoniously with the labor organizations in the industry, 
 and going no farther than to endeavor by every legitimate meas- 
 ure to further the interest of the affiliated employers. Such asso- 
 ciations are exceedingly helpful in furthering that regime of peace- 
 able collective bargaining to which most students of this subject 
 look forward as the ultimate outcome of present-day tendencies. 
 They are thus doing in an effective way the work of industrial 
 peace. Another group, however, illustrated by the National Metal 
 Trades Association, while they are temperate in tone and wage no 
 warfare on the labor organization as such, nevertheless maintain 
 certain fundamental principles which are directly in conflict with 
 the fundamental tenets of trades unionism. These associations, for 
 instance, maintain that the method of wage payment i.e. whether 
 wages shall be reckoned by the hour, the piece, or the premium 
 system is a matter which concerns the employer alone, and 
 they refuse to submit such questions to collective bargaining or 
 arbitration. Associations in the second group do not needlessly 
 foment strifes with the unions, but they regard industrial peace 
 as a consideration secondary to the maintenance of their funda- 
 
 2D
 
 402 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 mental principles, and accordingly they have been involved in a 
 number of protracted strikes and disputes. Finally, there is a 
 third group of employers' associations, of which the average citi- 
 zens' alliance is a good example, which may be correctly described 
 as " union smashers." Such associations have little regard for 
 the establishment of sound principles of collective bargaining, and 
 they are usually violently opposed to any recognition of organized 
 labor ; their aim is to weaken and harass their enemy, the labor 
 organization, whenever possible. 
 
 Owing to this difference of policy among the various employers' 
 associations, it is difficult to predict how the anti-labor movement 
 will affect that question in which the public interest is greatest 
 the question of industrial peace. For some little time, perhaps, 
 the militant enthusiasm of the more belligerent associations will 
 probably result in multiplying strikes and lockouts. In the end, 
 however, they will probably contribute effectively to the mainte- 
 nance of industrial peace by checking the more extortionate de- 
 mands of the unions and by securing that degree of organization 
 among employers which is necessary for the successful operation 
 of collective bargaining. If wage earners are to act in concert by 
 common or standard rules, it is evident that eventually they will 
 have to deal with an organized body of employers ; and the sooner 
 such organization of employers is perfected, the sooner will col- 
 lective bargaining be established as the regular method of deter- 
 mining conditions of employment. 
 
 The Agencies of Industrial Peace. Although collective bar- 
 gaining does not necessarily and in every instance operate to dis- 
 courage strikes, its net influence is unquestionably favorable to 
 the maintenance of industrial peace. Where a powerful trades 
 union exists, and the employers resolutely refuse to deal with it, 
 strikes are frequent. Where the opposite policy is pursued, and 
 the employers frankly recognize the union, strikes are infrequent. 
 Thus, there has been no great trouble for years in the stove foundry, 
 bituminous mining, and newspaper publishing industries, in which 
 general conventions between the respective labor and employers' 
 organizations are regularly held for the adoption of terms of em- 
 ployment for the ensuing year.
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 403 
 
 Trade Arbitration. In England, many, if not most, of these 
 recurrent conferences are based upon formal treaties, which pro- 
 vide for arbitration in case the two parties cannot come to an 
 agreement concerning terms. This is frequently referred to as 
 trade arbitration. But in the United States most of the general 
 conferences are based upon agreements which do not provide for 
 arbitration at all. Peace is maintained, although neither side 
 promises in any way to refrain from strikes or lockouts. Mutual 
 respect and free discussion prevent actual warfare. Indeed, many 
 authorities upon this subject are inclined to think that the intro- 
 duction of arbitration, even as a last resort, weakens the efficiency 
 of collective bargaining. It is almost always necessary for both 
 sides in collective bargaining to make some compromises ; and 
 this necessity imposes upon the representatives of the trades unions 
 the disagreeable duty of reporting to their constituents that they 
 have not secured the exact terms which they were instructed in 
 the beginning to demand. Because of this fact, if a provision for 
 arbitration exists, the union representatives are disposed to throw 
 the responsibility of disappointing their followers upon the shoul- 
 ders of the arbitrators. 
 
 Moreover, it has been pointed out that collective bargaining is 
 essentially inconsistent with arbitration. Collective bargaining is 
 commercial and elastic; it deals with the formulation of future 
 terms of employment; it looks to securing the best results possible; 
 it has no rational foundation save the willingness of the parties 
 concerned to get the most possible for their labor or their money, 
 as the case may be ; whereas arbitration is judicial in essence, and 
 its successful application implies the acceptance of some estab- 
 lished principle of wage adjustment, in the justice of which both 
 parties acquiesce. It is unfortunate but true that up to the pres- 
 ent time no one has ever formulated a doctrine of wage adjust- 
 ment which is at once workable and acceptable to a majority of 
 the people. Arbitration is a perfectly logical device, and works 
 successfully in the interpretation of minor difficulties growing out 
 of a broad agreement which has already been accepted. Or, if 
 both sides adopt some governing principle, it is perfectly possible 
 for a disinterested arbitrator to decide what this principle demands
 
 404 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 in a given situation. But as a helpful device in securing the ini- 
 tial adoption of a fundamental agreement, trade arbitration is be- 
 lieved to be illogical in principle and foredoomed in practice to 
 failure. 
 
 Voluntary Arbitration. There are, of course, many other kinds 
 of arbitration which have proved helpful in maintaining the in- 
 dustrial peace. Most advanced states now maintain boards of 
 conciliation and arbitration, whose business it is to prevent strikes 
 if possible, and to adjust or settle them after they occur. And 
 the Conciliation Department of the National Civic Federation has 
 also to its credit the prevention and settlement of a large number 
 of important strikes. But, for the most part, these voluntary 
 boards of conciliation and arbitration have shown little ability to 
 cope with the real situation. They have achieved enough to jus- 
 tify their existence, but not enough to warrant the acceptance of 
 voluntary arbitration as an adequate remedy for the evil. 
 
 Much more could be made of voluntary conciliation and arbitration than 
 has been made in the past. The short but very promising history of the 
 Canadian Industrial Disputes Investigation Act of 1907 suggests that a law 
 which, like the Canadian Act, forbade strikes and lockouts in important in- 
 dustries until an impartial board of conciliators had had time to investigate 
 the dispute and publish their recommendations and findings concerning the 
 equities of the case, would go far toward delivering us from the more injurious 
 industrial conflicts. The vital provisions of such a method of conciliation 
 are: (i) the prohibition of strikes and lockouts before and during the 
 investigation; (2) widespread publication of the findings of the board of in- 
 vestigation and conciliation; and (3) full permission to strike or lock out after 
 the publication of the findings. 1 
 
 Compulsory Arbitration. In New Zealand an even more radi- 
 cal remedy " compulsory arbitration " has been tried. Seven 
 workingmen in any industry may organize a union and lodge a 
 demand for better conditions of employment before arbitration 
 boards, whose decisions, when ratified by the supreme or central 
 court of arbitration, are absolute and binding. Similarly, any em- 
 ployer whose workmen are organized in a union may take a case 
 to the arbitration tribunals for settlement. An award of the cen- 
 
 1 An admirable description of the Canadian Act, from the pen of President 
 Eliot, may be found in McClwfs Magazine for December, 1907.
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 405 
 
 tral court of arbitration may be extended by the court to all com- 
 petitors of the original employer in the colony. In this way, com- 
 pulsory arbitration brings about the introduction of minimum 
 wages and other conditions of employment, established by the au- 
 thority of the state and enforced, not only by the watchful eyes oj 
 the parties concerned, but by the factory inspectors themselves. In 
 Victoria and South Australia much the same results are reached 
 through the agency of wage boards, containing representatives 
 of both the employers and their employees with a chairman se- 
 lected by these representatives or appointed by the government, 
 which are empowered to prescribe minimum wages and other 
 conditions of employment, that are enforced, as in New Zealand, 
 by the factory inspectors. Strikes, however, are not prohibited 
 under this system. 
 
 It is impossible to enter into a detailed discussion of either the 
 New Zealand or the Victoria system at this place. Both systems 
 have been in operation since 1896, both have been extended to 
 other Australian colonies, and both have been partially successful. 
 But the probability that either system will be introduced into this 
 country is so small as to make their discussion unnecessary here. 
 Both systems would conflict with our constitutional law, and both 
 would at the present time be regarded as entirely too radical by 
 the American people. Moreover, a large majority of trades union- 
 ists in this country are strongly opposed to compulsory arbitra- 
 tion. The significance of the New Zealand and Australian move- 
 ment is found in the regulation by the state of the rate of wages. 
 
 The Ultimate Solution. In arriving at a decision concerning 
 the measures which ought to be taken to maintain industrial peace, 
 it should be remembered that strikes are much more destructive 
 and dangerous in some industries than in others, and that here, as 
 in most other economic problems, it is dangerous to proceed on 
 general principles. In most industries, in our opinion, the strike 
 question may safely be left to the enlightened self-interest of the 
 parties concerned, trusting to collective bargaining and the work 
 of voluntary arbitration to prevent an excessive amount of war. 
 In small competitive industries the peaceful strike is not neces- 
 sarily an alarming phenomenon.
 
 406 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Slowly and surely, however, the opinion is gathering force that 
 in those industries which vitally touch the public welfare (such as 
 the anthracite coal industry, railway transportation, and the like) 
 the public ought, and by an exercise of legal ingenuity might, find 
 means to preserve the peace whether the two parties immediately 
 concerned desire peace or not. Compulsory arbitration in com- 
 petitive industries would unquestionably be unconstitutional in 
 this country. But with quasi-public industries, " industries af 
 fected by a public interest," the question is entirely different. If, 
 because of their monopolistic character and their intimate connec- 
 tion with the convenience of the public, the legislature may regu- 
 late the service and the rates of such industries, it would seem to 
 follow even more clearly that the legislature may adopt any meas- 
 ure necessary to prevent the utter cessation of such industries by 
 strikes and lockouts. If, for instance, the fare charged by a 
 street railway may be regulated by the state, in order to prevent 
 monopolistic extortion, how much more justifiable would be the 
 action of the state in preventing the complete interruption of the 
 traffic of the railway by means of a strike or lockout ! We cannot 
 pursue this topic in detail, but must close the discussion with a 
 simple expression of belief that compulsory arbitration for indus- 
 tries affected by a public use would be constitutional and prac- 
 ticable. 
 
 Profit Sharing. Profit sharing attempts, not to provide a 
 remedy for industrial disputes, but to anticipate and prevent them 
 by assigning to the employees a share of the profits fixed in ad- 
 vance. It is held that this arrangement enlists the employees' inter- 
 est in the success of the business, makes them more economical, 
 and so increases their zeal and efficiency that the share of profits 
 which they receive does not reduce in the long run the earnings of 
 the employer. In other words, the employees create the fund 
 from which their bonus is paid. This bonus may be paid in many 
 different ways : either in cash at the end of the business year, or 
 in shares of stock in the company in question, thus making the 
 workman partial owner of the business; or it may be amassed in 
 a savings or insurance fund, from which in his old age the work- 
 man receives a pension, or his family an annuity or cash premium
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 407 
 
 at the time of his death. The last method of profit sharing is 
 usually spoken of as deferred participation. 
 
 Neither historical study nor theoretical analysis of profit shar- 
 ing furnishes reasonable ground for the belief that this method of 
 industrial remuneration will ever play an important part in solv- 
 ing the modern labor problem. The principle of profit sharing 
 was recognized by the French economist and statesman, Turgot, 
 in 1775, but the first permanently successful experiment in profit 
 sharing was begun by the celebrated French firm of Leclaire in 
 1842. By 1878, 120 cases were known to be in existence; in 1891, 
 about 300; in 1900, probably no more were in existence than in 
 1891, although one authority fixes the number at 400. In the 
 United States, at the present time, the system is employed in 
 probably no more than twenty establishments. Since 1896, more- 
 over, and particularly in England, the number of firms which 
 regularly share profits with their employees has fallen off ; and con- 
 fidence in the system as a method of solving the labor problem is 
 unquestionably diminishing. 
 
 The reasons why profit sharing has not proved more successful 
 are various. In the first place, it has incurred the enmity of most 
 labor leaders, who oppose it because it has often been introduced 
 after a disastrous strike as an antidote to trades unionism, and be- 
 cause they believe that it stimulates the men to work beyond their 
 strength, and eventually results as overspeeding always re- 
 sults in reduced wages. 
 
 In the second place, it is illogical and inconsistent as explained 
 by most of its advocates. The latter assert that the workmen 
 create the fund from which their dividends are paid by increased 
 care, zeal, and speed. If this be true, and the system can hardly 
 prove a permanent success unless it is true, the end which profit 
 sharing seeks would be better achieved by the piece rate or gain- 
 sharing methods of wage payment. By both of these methods 
 the worker gets his premium for extra zeal and efficiency as part 
 of his wage, not as a gift; gets it on pay day, not at the end of the 
 year; and feels as free to bargain and higgle about the size of the 
 premium as he does about the size of the wage. Moreover, his 
 premium cannot be dissipated by unwise management or dishon-
 
 408 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 esty on the part of the employer, and it cannot be lost by reason 
 of his death, discharge, or change of employment. 
 
 Profit sharing has failed because it is unbusinesslike and smacks 
 of philanthropy. The average employer consciously or uncon- 
 sciously expects something in return for the dividends which he 
 distributes. And if he does expect a return, it is far better that 
 he should pay for it by a method which is certain, fixed by contract 
 or bargain in advance, and paid, not at long intervals, during 
 which it is threatened by the varying fortunes of the business, 
 but at the end of the week or month when ordinary wages 
 are paid. Of course, if in addition to fair wages the employer 
 wishes to distribute a gratuitous dividend at the end of the year, 
 for which he expects nothing in return, the employee is not likely 
 to object, and the generosity of the employer will probably do no 
 harm. But such a system of profit sharing cannot be expected 
 to become prevalent throughout a competitive commercial system 
 in which most employers cannot be philanthropists, even if they 
 desire. Moreover, human nature is so constituted that gifts of 
 this kind create in the mind of the giver an inevitable expectation 
 of recompense. 
 
 Industrial Democracy. The industrial organization of the 
 past was despotic. The despotic principle, the one-man power, 
 is an excellent thing in its own time and place. It gives to indus- 
 try the elasticity, celerity, and general efficiency which come from 
 singleness of aim; and in industry, despotism has continued longer 
 than in the political sphere. But it is merely a phase of develop- 
 ment and ought not to be regarded as final. Elsewhere the des- 
 potic principle has been softened or dissipated, in politics, in 
 religion, in the family, and eventually this discordant element 
 is bound to disappear or undergo serious modification in industry. 
 The whole labor movement is a concerted and united effort to 
 achieve industrial democracy, which means self-rule, self-control, 
 the self -direction of the masses in their efforts to gain a livelihood. 
 It is primarily because profit sharing means a departure from, 
 and not an approach toward, industrial democracy that we are 
 forced to reject it as a progressive step in accomplishing those 
 ends which the labor movement is inaugurated to achieve. A
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 409 
 
 far more consistent method of securing self-government is found 
 in cooperation. 
 
 Cooperation is of two kinds, coercive and voluntary. Coer 
 cive cooperation, which implies a partial or complete application 
 of socialism, is discussed in another chapter. 
 
 Voluntary cooperation takes many different forms, among 
 which we may distinguish: (i) distributive or consumers' coop- 
 eration, sometimes spoken of as cooperative buying; (2) coopera- 
 tive borrowing or cooperative credit; (3) cooperative marketing; 
 and (4) producers' or pure cooperation. 
 
 Consumers' or distributive cooperation has no necessary con- 
 nection with the transportation of goods, but refers merely to a 
 method of retail or wholesale exchange. Purchasers of groceries, 
 dry goods, and the like come together to purchase what they 
 need, and thus eliminate profits. They form a stock company, 
 subscribe for shares, employ a manager and clerks, who often 
 do not even share in the profits, and start a business. Divi- 
 dends are sometimes paid only on shares, but the approved way 
 is to pay a moderate interest on capital and to divide profits 
 among the customers in proportion to their purchases, the division 
 being made at the end of stated intervals. Usually a larger divi- 
 dend is distributed to shareholders than to ordinary customers; 
 and in some cases the employees receive as large a bonus as the 
 shareholders. Profits are thus said to be divided among capital, 
 custom, and labor. But so far as labor is concerned, the most 
 that can be said is that it receives a small share of the earnings; 
 labor does not cooperate in the sense that it has an important 
 voice in the management of the business. The scheme is one 
 of distributive cooperation plus profit sharing, not one of pure 
 cooperation. 
 
 Cooperative credit and cooperative marketing are familiar 
 phenomena in the United States the first in the form of the 
 well-known building and loan association; the second in the form 
 of fruit growers' association, cooperative elevator companies, and 
 the like, formed for the purpose of securing better terms and facili- 
 ties from railroads, commission houses, and middlemen in general. 
 In 1902-1903, for instance, there were 5299 building and loan
 
 410 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 associations in the United States, with a membership of 1,530,707, 
 and total assets of $577,228,014. About the same time (1902) 
 there were also 994 cooperative telephone companies, operating 
 89,300 instruments. 
 
 The good which these cooperative associations have accom- 
 plished is enormous, and there can be no doubt of their practi- 
 cability. They have not only proved commercially profitable to 
 the participators, but they have trained them to "team work" 
 and inculcated the spirit of mutual concession, the give and take 
 of concerted endeavor, which makes for social solidarity and con- 
 stitutes such an indispensable element of good citizenship in a 
 democratic state. 
 
 But they have done little and promised to do little in solving 
 the labor problem or in essentially improving the distribution of 
 wealth. They are, for the most part, composed of small capi- 
 talists, farmers, or salaried men, not wage earners, and in 
 organization differ little from democratically managed stock 
 companies of the usual type. Many, if not most, of the market- 
 ing associations are profit-making concerns whose employees 
 have no more voice in the selection of their bosses, and no more 
 share in the management of the business, than the employees of 
 an ordinary corporation. Even in the British cooperative socie- 
 ties the employees have no share in the management, and though 
 some of the associations notably the Scottish Wholesale So- 
 ciety indulge in a mild species of profit sharing with their 
 employees, the result is not industrial democracy, not self-govern- 
 ment, but merely joint-buying plus a paternalistic scheme of profit 
 sharing. The limits of the success of the British cooperative 
 movement are suggested by the fact that the employees of the 
 cooperative societies have formed themselves into a trades union 
 for the betterment of their condition of employment. 
 
 While consumers' cooperation and cooperative marketing 
 both designed to abolish the profits of the middleman are 
 important and praiseworthy forms of economic association, they 
 have little effect upon the wage-earning classes, and offer no 
 remedy for the antagonism between capital and labor in manu- 
 facturing industries. The variety of cooperation which really
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 411 
 
 copes with these questions and seriously attempts to regenerate 
 the wage system is producers' cooperation. The essential fea- 
 tures of this form of cooperation are (i) that each group of workers 
 is to be associated by their own free choice; (2) that these asso- 
 ciates shall work under a leader elected and removable by them- 
 selves ; and (3) that the collective remuneration of the labor per- 
 formed by the group shall be divided among all its members 
 (including the leader) in such a manner as shall be arranged, 
 upon principles recognized as equitable by the society them- 
 selves. 1 
 
 Successful cooperative experiments fulfilling the above con- 
 ditions are seldom met with. They are not unknown. Here and 
 there a man of transcendent commercial genius and extraordi- 
 nary sympathy has succeeded in democratizing his business, 
 turning it over to his employees and so impressing his spirit and 
 his methods upon his successors that the business continues to 
 prosper under the regime of self-government. An illustration 
 is found in the Godin Famttistere of Guise, France, which, begin- 
 ning with a scheme of profit sharing in 1877, has finally resulted 
 in the establishment not only of a cooperative manufacturing 
 enterprise, but in the successful conduct of what practically 
 amounts to a cooperative community. 
 
 But such cases are rare. Most experiments in producers' co- 
 operation have failed, and we fear they must continue to fail. 
 They simply cannot meet the competition of businesses organized 
 in the ordinary way, directed by one man or set of men with all 
 the efficiency, mobility, and adaptability that come from single- 
 ness of aim and undivided management. Industrial democracy, 
 as achieved in the cooperative form of industrial organization, is 
 too unwieldy, too slow, too mechanical. Multitudinous manage- 
 ment means relatively uncertain, indecisive, and inefficient man- 
 agement. 
 
 A modified form of producers' cooperation is not unknown among the 
 manufacturing industries of this country. An approximate idea of the extent 
 of this form of industrial organization may be gathered from recent census 
 statistics. In 1905 the statistics of manufactures relating to form of busi- 
 
 1 Schloss, Methods of Industrial Remuneration, p. 228.
 
 4 I2 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ness organization show a separate class of " miscellaneous business organiza- 
 tions" which we are told consists almost entirely of cooperative manufactur- 
 ing concerns. There were in this group 3203 establishments (constitut- 
 ing 1.5 per cent of all manufacturing establishments) with a capital of 
 $20,729,744 (0.2 per cent of the aggregate capital), employing 8520 persons 
 (0.2 per cent of all wage earners), producing goods with an annual value of 
 $54,466,028 (0.4 per cent of the aggregate product). Most of these associa- 
 tions are cooperative creameries ; and it is interesting to note that in this great 
 industry which was cooperative in origin the proportion of cooperative 
 concerns is steadily diminishing. These figures furnish a maximum estimate 
 of producers' cooperation in the United States, and a large majority of the 
 concerns credited to cooperation in this enumeration would fail to satisfy 
 a strict definition of producers' cooperation. For the most part they rep- 
 resent a form of cooperation among farmers and small capitalists who 
 stand on an equality as among themselves, but give their employees no real 
 share in the management of the business. 
 
 The wage system, whatever its defects, has one striking virtue 
 certainty. The wage earner knows what to expect and gets 
 what he expects. He is insured against risk of loss, and although 
 he may pay too high a price for his insurance, the insurance itself 
 is a highly desirable thing. It is one of the weaknesses of pro- 
 ducers' cooperation that the workman is encouraged to invest 
 his savings in the hazardous competitive experiments in which 
 he is engaged. He becomes part owner of the enterprise, to be 
 sure, but by doing so he assumes the risk of failure, a risk which, 
 other things being equal, it is desirable to eliminate. It is probable 
 that the ultimate method by which industrial democracy is achieved 
 will retain that feature of the present wage system by which most 
 of the workers are insured against business losses. 
 
 Indeed, we expect to see industrial democracy achieved through 
 the labor organization. Since the formation of the trades union 
 and the introduction of collective bargaining, the range of this 
 bargaining has constantly widened. Beginning with questions of 
 wages, hours of labor, and apprenticeship, it has gradually spread, 
 until at the present time some unions bargain about the sanitary 
 conditions of the work, the introduction of safety devices, the em- 
 ployment of women, the use of machinery, and the status of the 
 men with whom their members work. A very few powerful 
 unions insist that the foreman under whom their members work
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 413 
 
 shall belong to the union, demand a voice in the discharge of em- 
 ployees, and try to force the employer, when taking on new men, 
 to select them in order from lists of unemployed journeymen 
 prepared by the union. These demands, of course, may be harm- 
 ful; the working classes will have to learn by experience what 
 measure of control it is best to have in the hands of the employer. 
 The fact that power may be abused, however, is really beside the 
 point. The point lies in the possibility, and in general the desira- 
 bility, of extending the range of collective bargaining until the 
 employees shall have a voice and it is to be hoped a prevailing 
 voice in determining all the conditions of employment. Through 
 collective bargaining the control of the employees over the busi- 
 ness may be indefinitely expanded. Once having secured control, 
 the majority will learn, as they have in political life, to leave certain 
 particularly delicate questions to their industrial captains. In 
 the past, labor has had to seek capital and serve it. In the future, 
 capital may have to seek arid serve labor. The past may be 
 pictured by the single entrepreneur with his capital hiring a thou- 
 sand men to do his bidding. The future may behold the thou- 
 sand hiring the entrepreneur and his capital to do their bidding. 
 And the latter is the more pleasing, the more democratic, and 
 altogether the more wholesome picture. 
 
 These words are written in no spirit of advocacy, and with no 
 intention of palliating the obvious shortcomings of the trades 
 union. But the fact remains whether we like it or not that 
 economic theory and economic history unite in the conclusion 
 that the union has come to stay as long as the system of capi- 
 talistic production. The union must be improved, it cannot be 
 extirpated; and the most urgent task of the present is to con- 
 vince employers and unionists that there will be no real peace 
 until employers acknowledge the inevitableness of the union, 
 and unions acknowledge sympathetically and in practical 
 ways the social serviceableness of the employer. Trades unions 
 have been guilty of many sins violence, monopoly, political 
 corruption. But their gravest danger at the present time is a 
 false philosophy, in accordance with which many unionists have 
 come to believe that the best way to help the union is to oppose
 
 414 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the employer. This is not true of the more wisely conducted 
 unions. The railway brotherhoods frequently unite with the rail- 
 way managers in securing legislation favorable to the railway 
 industry; and the history of the National Civic Federation, for 
 example, proves that a number of the opposing leaders are keenly 
 aware that capital and labor have interests in common as well 
 as in opposition. In some way, however, united labor as a whole 
 has got to learn this lesson how to drive just as favorable a 
 bargain as possible with the employers in the first instance, and 
 then, the bargain having been made, to bend every effort in loyal 
 cooperation with the employer to make the business the greatest 
 possible success. This is not mere platitude. In the long run, 
 and whether we like the fact or not, productive efficiency is the 
 supreme economic virtue; and the institution that stands in its 
 way will perish. The trades union must bring into industry 
 something besides conflict, or it will disappear. The union that 
 so conducts itself as to make the non-union man or the non-union 
 shop more efficient than the union man or the union shop, in the 
 long run, simply puts a premium upon the suppression of union- 
 ism. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Is the industrial or the trades union the more logical form of organiza- 
 tion ? Can the two be reconciled ? Mention as many kinds of jurisdiction 
 disputes as you can. 
 
 2. Does the trades union rest upon a sound economic basis? Is it likely 
 to endure? Is it in any large degree responsible for the conflict between 
 labor and capital? 
 
 3. Are all attempts to achieve a monopoly illegitimate? Is there more 
 justification for labor monopolies than industrial monopolies ? 
 
 4. Is the policy of the closed shop ever justifiable ? Intimidation of non- 
 union men ? restriction of apprenticeship ? regulation of output ? 
 
 5. The strike has been defined as a " concerted cessation of work " ; is 
 this definition correct? Have men a "right" to strike whenever they wish? 
 Are employers justified in "locking out" their men at pleasure? 
 
 6. Are "organized" strikes more successful than "unorganized" strikes? 
 Are strikes more or less successful than formerly ? Do they last longer ? 
 
 7. Is the "blacklist" more justifiable than the boycott? Can either the 
 " blacklist " or the boycott be conducted in a lawful manner ? 
 
 8. Distinguish between trade arbitration, voluntary arbitration, "com-
 
 LABOR PROBLEMS 415 
 
 pulsory investigation," and compulsory arbitration. What are the defects 
 of arbitration as a method of settling labor disputes? 
 
 9. Why do labor leaders oppose compulsory arbitration? Is their op- 
 position a sufficient reason for rejecting it ? Why is the plea for compulsory 
 arbitration particularly strong in the case of monopolistic industries ? 
 
 10. How does "gain sharing" differ from "profit sharing"? Is profit 
 sharing necessarily paternalistic ? If so, is this a defect ? 
 
 11. Does consumers' cooperation materially advance industrial democ- 
 racy ? Is producers' cooperation likely to grow and expand ? 
 
 12. How can a large measure of industrial control be secured for the wage 
 earner through the trades union ? Other things being equal, is it desirable 
 that the wage earner should secure a large measure of control ? Is it per- 
 missible to assume that other things will be "equal"? 
 
 LITERATURE 
 
 ADAMS, T. S., and SUMNER, H. L. Labor Problems. 
 
 BOOTH, CHARLES. Life and Labor of the People in London. 
 
 BROOKS, JOHN GRAHAM. The Social Unrest. 
 
 Bureau of Labor (U.S.). Bulletin Annual and Special Reports of the 
 
 Commission of Labor. 
 
 COMMONS, JOHN R. Trade Unionism and Labor Problems. 
 ELY, RICHARD T. The Labor Movement in America. 
 OILMAN, N. P. Methods of Industrial Peace; A Dividend to Labor. 
 HALL, P. F. Immigration. 
 
 Industrial Commission (U.S.). Report, Vols., XVII and XIX. 
 LEVASSEUR, E. The American Workman. 
 MITCHELL, JOHN. Organized Labor. 
 
 ROWNTREE, B. SEEBOHM. Poverty: A Study of Town Life. 
 SCHLOSS, D. F. Methods of Industrial Remuneration. 
 WEBB, CATHERINE. Industrial Cooperation. 
 WEBB, BEATRICE and SIDNEY. History of Trade Unionism; Industrial 
 
 Democracy.
 
 CHAPTER XXIV 
 INTEREST 
 
 INTEREST is the price paid for the services of capital. It appears 
 in two forms: loan interest, the amount paid by one man to another 
 for the use of money or goods owned by the latter, and imputed 
 interest, that portion of the value of the products of industry which 
 is attributed or imputed to the services of capital, as distinct from 
 the services of land and labor. Interest is usually measured as a 
 percentage of the money value of capital, and this, coupled with 
 the fact that capital is often lent in the form of money, has led to 
 the prevalence of the idea that interest is a payment for the use of 
 money. This is only a partial description of interest, however, 
 for it does not include imputed interest nor the loan interest paid 
 for the use of many forms of capital buildings, for example. 
 
 Objections to Interest Taking. It is only in modern times that interest 
 has been generally considered a legitimate and necessary form of income. 
 The strong denunciations of usury contained in both the Old and New Testa- 
 ments are denunciations of interest taking, for the word "usury" formerly 
 meant any kind of interest, and not merely excessive interest, as at present. 
 The opinion of many classical writers is illustrated by Aristotle's dictum that 
 " money was intended to be used in exchange, but not to increase at interest." 
 During the greater part of the middle ages the authority and teaching of the 
 church was set definitely against the taking of interest in any form. In the 
 middle of the fourteenth century the prohibition of usury was incorporated 
 in the civil law. These objections, however, had reference chiefly to loan 
 interest, and interest on money lent for personal use at that ; for capital was 
 not thought of as one of the factors in production until comparatively modern 
 times. In fact, by the fifteenth century, when opportunities for the profitable 
 use of money had appeared in such forms as the purchase of rights to receive 
 land rents, or partnership ventures in trade (where interest was held to be 
 justified by the risk incurred), the canonists (the writers on church law) 
 admitted the legitimacy not only of such gainful employments of money, 
 
 416
 
 INTEREST 417 
 
 but also, in many cases, of interest on loans. The justification of loan inter- 
 est took on at first many curious forms. It was regarded in some cases as 
 a fine for delay in the repayment of the loan, so that lenders often resorted 
 to the subterfuge of lending money gratuitously for a nominal period, the 
 real agreement being that they were to get back their money principal, with 
 a fine for the delay added, at a later date. In other cases loan interest was 
 justified as a payment for the loss of the possible gains which the lender 
 might have got by using his money himself. Usury, which at first meant any 
 kind of loan interest, came to mean interest on money loans to relieve per- 
 sonal needs, rather than for gainful employment, then interest on loans in 
 which the element of risk was lacking, and finally, excessively high interest. 
 To-day the use of capital is so prominent a feature of our productive meth- 
 ods that the legitimacy of interest is not generally questioned. Socialistic 
 writers, however, insist that interest is only a result of the system of the private 
 ownership of capital, and that with the abolition of private property in pro- 
 duction goods what is now counted as interest would become part of the wages 
 of labor. It is accordingly important that we should understand clearly 
 why interest has to be paid, as well as that we should study the factors de- 
 termining the rate of interest. We shall find, however, that the explanation 
 of the necessity of interest is really a part of the explanation of the rate of 
 interest. 
 
 Inadequate Explanations of Interest. An idea that naturally 
 suggests itself is that interest has to be paid for the use of money 
 because "money can be profitably employed in business." This 
 explanation, which is very much like one of the ways in which the 
 canonists finally came to justify interest, is obviously inadequate. 
 It is only an attempt to explain loan interest by assuming the exist- 
 ence of imputed interest. What we want to know is why " money 
 can be profitably employed in business." 
 
 A similar, but somewhat more definite, attempt at an explanation 
 is contained in the statement that interest is paid because capital 
 is productive. It is pointed out that by the use of capital goods 
 the product of industry is greatly increased over what could be 
 produced by labor and land alone. This is, of course, true, but 
 taken alone it does not explain interest. The problem of interest 
 relates to the value of the product, not to the amount of the product. 
 There is nothing in the mere quantity of the product that gives 
 value to it. The farmers of this country have found more than 
 once that a large wheat crop has sold for less .in the aggregate 
 than a small one. The real problem of interest is this: Why 
 
 2E
 
 418 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 can an entrepreneur, by the use of capital, increase the selling 
 value of his product enough to not only pay for the capital actually 
 used up in production, but also to pay in addition a surplus in the 
 form of interest upon the capital employed? Nor can we say 
 that " capital produces interest." It cannot be too strongly em- 
 phasized that neither land, nor labor, nor capital produces value. 
 They are simply the instruments used in the production of things 
 that are valuable because they satisfy human wants, and hence 
 command a price in the market. Part of the value of the product 
 is imputed or attributed to capital in the form of interest, and it is 
 because of its capacity to earn interest that capital is valued. To 
 say that capital produces value is to reverse the true process. 
 Capital goods produce (or aid in the production of) other goods, 
 and the value of these produced goods is the cause of capital 
 value. 
 
 Why Interest can be Paid. We shall find the analysis of our 
 problem somewhat simpler if we divide it into two parts: first, 
 why interest is possible; and second, why interest must be paid. 
 In discussing why interest can be paid, we shall assume that in- 
 terest must be paid if capital is to be used in production, reserving 
 the discussion of the legitimacy of this assumption for the follow- 
 ing section. 
 
 It is the physical productivity of capital the fact that capital 
 can be used in cooperation with land and labor in the production 
 of goods that makes it possible for the entrepreneur to look upon 
 part of his total money income as interest on his investment of 
 capital. Now, as we have seen, the mere fact that capital is pro- 
 ductive in the physical sense does not explain interest, but the fact 
 that capital is used under the guidance of entrepreneurs in the pro- 
 duction of wealth does explain the possibility of interest. The 
 mere physical productivity of land does not explain rent land 
 will grow weeds as well as wheat; nor does the mere physical 
 productivity of labor explain wages some men have put years 
 into the construction of perpetual-motion machines that are abso- 
 lutely worthless. But it is the business of the entrepreneur to see 
 that land and labor are used wisely; and from his point of view 
 they are used wisely if they are used in the production of things
 
 INTEREST 419 
 
 that consumers want, and want intensely enough to pay such prices 
 as will enable the entrepreneur to pay the rent of the land and the 
 wages of the labor employed. Similarly, an entrepreneur will 
 not employ capital in any kind of production unless the prices he 
 expects to get for his products are such as to cover the expenses 
 incurred in the use of capital. Nor will he knowingly use so much 
 capital that his product will sell for less than a smaller product 
 would have sold for, any more than he will knowingly produce an 
 unprofitably large quantity of goods by the use of too much labor 
 or too much land. 
 
 On the one hand, the entrepreneur has to estimate the prices he 
 will get for his products; on the other hand, he has to estimate the 
 productivity and the expense of land, labor, and capital. The 
 expense of capital includes, first, the cost of the capital actually 
 used up in production; and second, interest on all of the capital 
 used, whether " used up " or not (assuming, as previously ex- 
 plained, the necessity of interest). The principles that will guide 
 the entrepreneur as to the relative proportions of labor, land, and 
 capital he will use have already been discussed in connection with 
 the general subject of diminishing productivity. We may, how- 
 ever, emphasize again the fact that productivity must be attributed, 
 not to " capital in general," but to specific units of specific kinds 
 of capital, used in connection with a definite amount of land and 
 labor; the productivity imputed to any particular unit of capital 
 being the precise amount of product actually dependent upon the 
 use of that particular unit the amount by which the total prod- 
 uct would be decreased if the unit in question were not used. An 
 entrepreneur will increase his use of capital rather than of labor 
 or land, when a given expense for any kind of capital will add more 
 to his product than would a similar expense for labor or land. 
 
 The Necessity of Interest. Free goods, such as air or the force 
 of gravitation, are productive in the physical sense, in that they are 
 absolutely necessary to most forms of production. The surface 
 of Lake Michigan is used in producing the service of transporta- 
 tion in essentially the same way as is capital in the form of a rail- 
 way roadbed and track. But we cannot impute productivity to 
 specific units of free goods, for the simple reason that the amount
 
 420 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of the product is not dependent on the utilization of any one unit 
 of them. Any one cubic foot of air could be dispensed with; we 
 cannot even conceive of the force of gravitation as limited in quan- 
 tity; the great lakes furnish pathways that are more than sufficient 
 for all the vessels that traverse them. We do impute productivity 
 to the better lands that are used in production, because any one 
 acre of them could not be withdrawn from use without a diminu- 
 tion in the product. The controlling reason for this difference Is 
 that the spontaneous supply of free goods is in excess of the use 
 that is made of them; while the supply of the better lands is lim- 
 ited as compared with the demand for them. This suggests at 
 once why productivity has to be imputed to specific units of capi- 
 tal, and that is, that the supply of capital is limited. 
 
 Why is the supply of capital limited ? This question leads us to 
 examine the nature of the supply of capital. Imagine a society 
 without capital carrying on its productive processes by the use of 
 labor and land only. So long as the members of this community 
 produce only what they consume directly, or (if, despite the ab- 
 sence of capital, money economy and a system of exchange may 
 be imagined to prevail) so long as they spend all their money in- 
 comes for things used up immediately in the satisfaction of their 
 wants, there will be no accumulation of capital. In order that 
 capital shall be furnished, it is necessary that some members of the 
 community turn aside from the production of things that are used 
 in the immediate satisfaction of their wants and devote their time 
 to the production of goods that will be used in further production. 
 Whether they do this on their own account, or whether they are 
 paid for their work while they are doing it by others, some post- 
 ponement of the satisfaction of wants is necessary. In the one 
 case those who produce the capital goods give up temporarily the 
 satisfactions which they might have derived from the consump- 
 tion goods they could have produced. In the other case, those 
 who are devoting part of their money incomes to the payment of 
 those who are producing capital goods are giving up the immediate 
 satisfactions which they might have secured with the money. In 
 either case the production of capital involves the sacrifice of wait- 
 ing on the part of some members of the community. But why
 
 INTEREST 421 
 
 should waiting be called a sacrifice? Do not those who give up 
 present satisfactions in order that capital goods may be produced 
 get a full repayment if they get back in the form of the products 
 of their capital goods as much as they, for the time being, give up? 
 In other words, why should capital not be furnished for produc- 
 tive purposes if those who furnish the capital get back an exact 
 equivalent (in value) for the amount of capital they have supplied ? 
 Why should an extra payment, in the form of interest, be necessary 
 to induce saving? 
 
 The answer to these questions is found in the difference between 
 present and future values. Our present wants are more intense 
 than our present estimates of our future wants of a similar kind. 
 We visualize the present more vividly than we do the future; we 
 yield sometimes to the temptation of satisfying the more trivial 
 wants of the present, even when we know that we are thereby ren- 
 dering uncertain the satisfaction of more important wants in the 
 future; and when we take considerable periods of time into ac- 
 count, we may reasonably say that the uncertainty of life itself 
 gives us some ground for preferring present to possible future 
 satisfactions. Notwithstanding the vast difference between civ- 
 ilized men and savages in this respect, for many of the latter 
 seem to have absolutely no regard for future needs, the fact still 
 remains that waiting is a sacrifice, and in order to induce the sav- 
 ing that is a prerequisite to the use of capital in industry, a pre- 
 mium or reward for waiting has to be paid in the form of interest. 
 This fact is the most fundamental thing in the explanation of 
 interest. 
 
 It must not be inferred that, in the actual economic life of to-day, 
 no capital would be supplied if interest were not paid. There are 
 other motives that induce men to save parts of their incomes. 
 The desire to provide for old age and for such contingencies as 
 sickness and accident, or to make provision for one's family in 
 case of death, would result in a considerable amount of saving. 
 The mere pride of accumulation, and the fact that the satisfaction 
 of many important wants, such as the desire to own a house, or the 
 desire for foreign travel, necessitate the gradual accumulation of 
 what is to most persons a considerable sum of money, must also
 
 422 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 be given due weight. None of these motives would in themselves 
 induce men to invest or lend their saved funds in productive under- 
 takings if no interest at all were paid. In fact, this would be a 
 matter of indifference, for savings might just as well be hoarded. 
 But a very low interest premium would suffice to overcome this 
 indifference and to bring about their investment in productive 
 undertakings. Even this low interest rate, however, would be 
 sufficient to balance, in some additional cases, the difference be- 
 tween the intensity of present wants and the intensity of future 
 wants, so that in these cases, in turn, spending or saving would be a 
 matter of indifference an indifference that would in its turn be 
 overcome by a slight increase in the interest rate. In a similar 
 way every increase in the interest rate would induce more persons 
 to save and would induce many of those who were already saving 
 a part of their incomes to save a larger proportion of them. At 
 any given time, accordingly, the interest rate is considerably higher 
 than would be necessary to compensate for a large part of the wait- 
 ing that devolves upon those who furnish capital funds for pro- 
 ductive purposes. It is just high enough, however, to be a recom- 
 pense for marginal waiting, which is the waiting that would not 
 take place if the interest rate were any lower. If the interest rate 
 is 5 per cent, a dollar to-day is worth a dollar and five cents a 
 year from to-day, not to all savers, but to the marginal savers. 
 
 The Investment of Capital. We have seen that the supply of 
 capital originates in the fact that some people save part of their 
 money incomes, and that interest has to be paid in order to induce 
 this saving. Such persons are said to get an " income from their 
 capital." Strictly speaking, their savings are not productive capi- 
 ital at all, in the sense in which the word " productive " is used in 
 this book. Productive capital consists of the concrete material 
 instruments of production, such as factory buildings, machines, 
 raw materials, merchants' stocks of finished products, and the 
 like. Savings are not productive capital in this sense, but the 
 process by which they are transmuted into productive capital is a 
 simple and familiar one. The simplest case is where the entre- 
 preneur saves part of his own money income and uses his savings 
 in the purchase of additional capital goods, the value of the prod-
 
 INTEREST 423 
 
 ucts of which he estimates will be large enough to repay him for 
 his waiting, as well as to replace his capital as it is used up, that 
 is, to earn interest for him as well as repay the principal. Or, the 
 entrepreneur may borrow money directly from others who have 
 saved it, agreeing to pay annual interest, and in addition to repay 
 the amount of the loan the principal at some specified time. 
 In the complex economy of the present, however, it very often 
 happens that the entrepreneur who can use money profitably and 
 the man who has surplus funds to invest do not arrange the trans- 
 action directly. Savings are " placed at interest " in savings banks, 
 insurance companies, or other financial institutions, and it is to 
 such institutions that the entrepreneur who thinks that he can use 
 more capital profitably applies for loans. 
 
 Very often the entrepreneur is a corporation rather than an in- 
 dividual, but the same three methods of obtaining capital are open 
 to it. The corporation may choose to reinvest some of its net 
 earnings in productive forms of capital rather than to pay them all 
 out in dividends to its stockholders. In the bookkeeping of many 
 corporations, such savings on the part of the corporation are rep- 
 resented by the item called " surplus " on the balance sheet; in 
 other cases, especially with railways, it may happen that these 
 reinvestments of earnings are hidden by unduly enlarging the ac- 
 counting item of " maintenance " or upkeep of the plant, so that 
 it includes the expense of new additions of capital. When in need 
 of money to meet a temporary emergency, the corporation may 
 borrow from banks just as the individual entrepreneur does. 
 When in need of money for more permanent investment in the 
 durable forms of capital goods, the corporation usually issues its 
 own interest-bearing obligations in the form of bonds, which it 
 sells to banks, insurance companies, and other financial institu- 
 tions, as well as to individuals. Bond issues are only one way of 
 borrowing money. But whether the money funds are furnished by 
 the entrepreneur or by others, the formation of capital necessi- 
 tates, first, the saving of parts of money incomes, and second, the 
 use of the funds thus secured in the purchase of capital goods. 
 The expression " investment of capital " is used as a short way of 
 describing this twofold process.
 
 424 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The Replacement of Capital. It is clear, then, that saving, 
 which necessitates waiting, is a prerequisite to the formation of 
 neio capital, that is, to an increase of the supply of capital already 
 in existence. But at any given time the capital already in exist- 
 ence forms a very large proportion of the total supply of capital, 
 and it may be thought that the present interest rate does not affect 
 this portion of the supply. We must, however, take into consid- 
 eration the fact that almost all kinds of capital are being continu- 
 ally used up in production. This using up may be a matter of a 
 single use, as in the case of fuel or raw materials, or it may be a 
 gradual wearing out, as in the case of a machine, but such differ- 
 ences are differences in degree of durability rather than differ- 
 ences in kind. 
 
 As we have seen, the entrepreneur will not normally employ 
 any given additional unit of capital unless he expects to get enough 
 from the value of the added product to replace the capital actually 
 used up in production as well as to pay interest. This means that 
 if the entrepreneur's estimates prove correct, part of the money 
 income he gets for his product may be regarded as a replacement 
 fund, sufficient in amount to replace the capital used up in pro- 
 duction. We must not, however, make the error of thinking of 
 the replacement fund as definite in quantity. Whether or not any 
 unit of capital produces enough to furnish a replacement fund, 
 depends on whether the entrepreneur's estimate is a correct one. 
 There is no reason why unproductive forms of capital should be 
 kept intact in amount. He would be a foolish business man, for 
 instance, who would keep reinvesting a certain amount of money 
 in raw materials in the face of a diminishing demand for the fin- 
 ished product. Even if enough income is earned to form a re- 
 placement fund, the capital used up need not be replaced unless 
 the entrepreneur so chooses. A farmer may have saved for years 
 in order to buy a reaper. The reaper will enable him to raise 
 more wheat, or, possibly, to produce the same amount of wheat at 
 less expense. In either case it will mean an increase in his net 
 money income. He can, if he chooses, set aside enough of this 
 added income so that, when the first reaper wears out, his accumu- 
 lated funds will replace it. From one point of view we may say
 
 INTEREST 
 
 425 
 
 that in this way the reaper "replaces itself." But the farmer can, 
 if he prefers, use all of his increased income in the purchase of 
 additional comforts and luxuries for himself and his family. In 
 deciding whether he will replace his capital or increase his present 
 consumption, he will be guided by the same kind of an estimate 
 of the relative importance of present and future wants on the one 
 hand, and of the amount which the capital will add to his income, 
 on the other hand, that guided him in the original saving which 
 led to the purchase of the first reaper. 
 
 Similar illustrations can be found in other kinds of undertak- 
 ings. Many business enterprises have failed because business 
 men have "lived beyond their incomes" which often means 
 simply that they have not replaced their capital so rapidly as they 
 have used it up. Many American railways have maintained a 
 specious prosperity for many years by paying "unearned divi- 
 dends " ; that is, by letting their capital (roadbed, rolling stock, 
 buildings, etc.) deteriorate through not expending enough of their 
 gross income in the maintenance of their way and equipment. 
 
 The stock of capital in existence at any one time is the result of 
 past saving. But this stock of capital cannot be maintained intact 
 without more saving. From this point of view we may say that 
 the sacrifice of present goods for future goods which society un- 
 dergoes in order to reap the advantages of capitalistic production 
 is not something that is done "once for all," but is a continuous 
 sacrifice. 
 
 The Shifting of Investment. As a matter of fact, a large amount 
 of the capital that is used up in production is not replaced, for the 
 simple reason that entrepreneurs find that some particular kinds 
 of capital are not profitable; that is, they do not add enough to 
 the value of the entrepreneurs' total product to repay them for 
 their cost (including interest and replacement). It may happen 
 that the entrepreneur has been mistaken as to the technical effi- 
 ciency (or productivity) of his capital, or that he has overestimated 
 the demand for his products. New inventions or new methods of 
 production may lessen the income yielding power of part of the 
 existing stock of capital, or capricious changes in demand may 
 have a similar effect. On the other hand, these new methods of
 
 426 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 production and these changes in demand are making new forms 
 of capital profitable. Even if the "replacement fund" were a 
 definite and rigid annual sum, it would not be entirely devoted to 
 replacing the particular kinds of capital that had been used up in 
 production. There would be a continual shifting from the less 
 profitable to the more profitable forms of capital. 
 
 We often hear it said that capital is transferred from one indus- 
 try to another, or from one locality to another, or from one country 
 to another. Such expressions are misleading. Capital goods are 
 not usually transferred in this fashion, although in exceptional 
 cases it may happen. 1 These statements often mean that the 
 ownership of capital changes, as when a capitalist sells his holdings 
 in one industry to another capitalist and invests his own funds in 
 another undertaking. The most important way in which "capi- 
 tal is transferred " is through that gradual shifting in the forms of 
 investment which has just been described. 
 
 The Relation of the Durability of Capital Goods to Investment. 
 The ease with which investments of capital may be shifted 
 varies for different forms of capital. Especially important in this 
 connection is the durability of capital. As has been already sug- 
 gested, some forms of capital are destroyed as capital by a single 
 use. The fuel and raw materials used in a manufacturing estab- 
 lishment and the merchant's stock in trade belong to this category. 
 The merchant's stock in trade becomes consumption goods in the 
 hands of consumers: raw materials reappear in the finished prod- 
 uct, as do other forms of capital for that matter, although in a less 
 obvious sense. But the fact remains that these particular forms 
 of capital investments yield their services only once, and when they 
 are once used by the entrepreneur for the purpose for which they 
 were intended, they cease to be capital. 
 
 From such transient forms of capital we may pass by insensible 
 gradations to capital goods which yield a long succession of serv- 
 ices, the series culminating in such durable forms of capital as 
 
 1 For example, some generally used kinds of machinery (such as lathes, 
 milling or planing machines, engines, or motors) may be transferred from one 
 establishment in one industry to an establishment in another industry, or draft 
 horses may be sold by farmers to merchants.
 
 INTEREST 427 
 
 buildings used for productive purposes, or railway roadbeds. If a 
 particular form of capital lasts for exactly a year, the period of 
 time usually taken as a unit in the computation of the rate of inter- 
 est, estimating the expense of employing such capital is a very 
 simple matter. If, for example, the rate of interest is 6 per cent, 
 an entrepreneur would not invest $1000 in such capital unless he 
 estimated that it would increase his product by an amount that 
 would sell for at least $1060. In the case of the more transient 
 forms of capital, however, the computation is usually made by 
 taking into account the "rate of turnover." A manufacturer may 
 be continually buying raw materials and making them into fin- 
 ished products. If the raw materials purchased during a year cost 
 $3000, but if, on the average, only $1000 is invested in raw ma- 
 terials at any one time, the capital is said to be "turned over" 
 three times during the course of the year. The interest rate is 
 computed only on the average amount of capital "tied up," so 
 that interest of 2 per cent on each turnover would amount to 
 6 per cent on the actual investment of capital. 
 
 In the case of the more durable forms of capital the computa- 
 tion is more complicated. Here the entrepreneur has to take into 
 account not only the original expense of the capital good and the 
 amounts which it will add to his annual product, but also its dura- 
 bility, and the fact that a large part of the income which it will 
 earn for him is future income. This future income, as we have 
 seen, will not be valued so highly as the same amount of present 
 income would be. 
 
 Suppose, for example, that the entrepreneur is considering the purchase 
 of a machine which will be worn out in ten years, and the price of which is 
 $1000. If he wishes to get 6 per cent interest on his investment (possibly 
 because he has to pay that much for the money funds he uses), he cannot 
 afford to purchase the machine unless it will increase his annual product 
 during those ten years by an account that will sell for at least $136. For 
 $1000 is the present value of an annual payment of $136 for ten years, com- 
 puted on the basis of an annual interest rate of 6 per cent, compounded 
 annually. If he is satisfied with 5 per cent interest, a probable increase of 
 $130 in the annual value of his product would justify the investment. From 
 this point of view the investment of capital is, so far as the entrepreneur's 
 estimates prove correct, equivalent to the purchase of an annuity for a term of 
 years corresponding to the life of the capital good. Of course, as the capital
 
 428 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 wears out, its productivity is apt to decrease. Such things, together with 
 any probable changes on the salability of the product, as well as all other 
 contingencies that can be foreseen, have also to be taken into account by 
 the entrepreneur, and still further complicate the problem. 
 
 It is obvious that the entrepreneur does not usually make an elaborate 
 mathematical calculation of the kind suggested here. His business experi- 
 ence and knowledge of market conditions afford the basis for a more or lest 
 accurate guess as to the profitableness of a proposed investment of capital. 
 He estimates that a certain machine will or will not "earn its cost" (including 
 interest) because he knows something about the profitableness of the use of 
 similar machines in his own or other establishments. The concrete problem 
 that continually presents itself to the entrepreneur is simply that of getting 
 the maximum of salable product at the minimum cost. An investment in 
 a particular machine is usually judged (except in the case of new under- 
 takings), not by its profitableness as measured by an absolute standard, 
 but, its technical efficiency being known, by its profitableness (as to product 
 and costs) as inferred from the experience of the entrepreneur with his present 
 appliances and methods. 
 
 The same considerations hold true for investments in most other kinds of 
 capital goods. Nevertheless, a scientific and accurate analysis of the real 
 profitableness of an investment has to follow the lines that have been indicated 
 above. In fact, in the most scientific forms of investment (such as the pur- 
 chase and sale of large blocks of corporation bonds by dealers in such se- 
 curities), the results of elaborate actuarial calculations are utilized. That 
 such calculations are made by those who supply capital rather than by the 
 users of capital, comes from the fact that the supply of capital (so far as it is 
 not furnished by the entrepreneur himself) is under a definite contract on the 
 part of the entrepreneur as to the amount of interest to be paid and as to the 
 time when the principal is to be paid. In many such loans the element of 
 risk to the capitalist is almost entirely eliminated, and the calculation of the 
 present values of such investments becomes accordingly a simple matter of 
 mathematics. 
 
 The Expense and Value of Capital. When we speak of the cost 
 or expense of capital, we may have in mind either one of two dis- 
 tinct things. We may mean the price paid by the entrepreneur 
 for the loan of the money funds which he invests in specific kinds 
 of capital goods, or we may mean the prices paid for the capital 
 goods themselves. The first thing is, of course, loan interest; 
 the second is simply a matter of the market prices of commodities. 
 It is this second thing the market price of capital goods that 
 we wish to consider at this point. As commodities, these capital 
 goods come under the general laws of value and price, and most of
 
 INTEREST 429 
 
 what has been said in earlier chapters about the valuation of con- 
 sumption goods holds just as true in respect to the valuation of 
 these production goods. Their price at any given time is apt to 
 be fixed rather close to the point where demand and supply would 
 be in equilibrium. In the long run their values if they are not 
 patented products, but are competitively produced cannot get 
 very far away from the expenses of producing them. 
 
 But there is one fundamental difference which has been sug- 
 gested in other connections. Consumption goods are valued be- 
 cause they satisfy human wants, and the intensity of the wants 
 which particular units of goods satisfy have, through the law of 
 marginal utility, a very direct relation to their market values. 
 Capital goods do not satisfy human wants directly; they are val- 
 ued simply because they aid in the production of goods that do 
 satisfy human wants directly. 1 The demand for them, as we have 
 seen, is the entrepreneurs' interpretation of the demand for their 
 products. The law of diminishing productivity bears about the 
 same relation to the determination of their values that the law of 
 diminishing utility does to the determination of the values of con- 
 sumption goods. As in the case of the demand for labor, the 
 elasticity of the demand for a particular sort of capital goods is 
 affected not only by the fact that the higher the cost of the capital, 
 the higher will have to be the price of the product, and, conse- 
 quently, the smaller will be the quantity of the product, that can be 
 sold, but also by the fact that when the cost of any variety of capi- 
 tal goods is relatively high, the entrepreneurs will economize in 
 the use of that particular kind of capital and will use relatively 
 more labor, relatively more land, and relatively more of the other 
 forms of capital. The first of these facts is a corollary of the law 
 
 1 Here as elsewhere in the present discussion of interest, no account is taken 
 of the obvious fact that many kinds of capital goods are used in the production 
 of other capital goods, rather than in the production of consumption goods 
 directly. There may be in many cases a large number of steps in the productive 
 process before the final goal the satisfaction of human wants is reached. 
 A consideration of these facts would only make the analysis more involved, 
 without changing in the slightest degree the conclusions reached. They are, 
 however, taken into account in the discussion of the "social dividend," in 
 Chapter XXV.
 
 430 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of diminishing utility, the second, a corollary of the law of dimin- 
 ishing productivity. 
 
 This analysis of the value of capital goods relates, however, only 
 to the supply of new capital goods. After capital is once definitely 
 invested in industry, its value is determined solely by its ability to 
 earn an income for its owner. If the entrepreneur has overesti- 
 mated the technical efficiency of a machine or the salability of its 
 products, that is, if he has overestimated its income-yielding 
 power, he may find that its value is less than the price he held for 
 it. Here, however, we have to note an important distinction be- 
 tween free capital and specialized capital. By free capital we mean 
 capital that has a number of different possible uses, or that can be 
 transferred from one industry or one establishment to another. 
 Specialized capital is capital that can be used for only one purpose, 
 and that cannot be transferred from one establishment or industry 
 to another. 
 
 The capital invested in the construction of a railway roadbed, 
 or in the digging of an irrigation ditch, is absolutely specialized. 
 The roadbed and the irrigation ditch are of use only in connection 
 with the particular transportation or agricultural undertakings 
 for which they were constructed. If the undertakings should fail, 
 the value of these specialized forms of capital would be absolutely 
 wiped out. A manufacturing firm may invest a large amount of 
 money in new models of specially designed machinery. If the 
 new machines prove unsuccessful, their value may sink to what 
 they will sell for as scrap iron. On the other hand, we have free 
 capital in such forms as tools, machines of the standard models 
 that are used in different establishments in the same industry, or 
 even in different industries ; raw materials that can be made up 
 into different kinds of finished products and the like. A farmer 
 who stocks his farm with dairy cattle, but finds his land unsuited 
 for a dairy farm, does not incur a total loss on his investment, for 
 he can sell his cattle to some farmer who can make profitable use 
 of them. The distinction here emphasized is only one of degree. 
 We have capital in a considerable variety of forms that are partly 
 free and partly specialized. Such capital is capital that is best 
 adapted to one specific purpose, but which may also be put to
 
 INTEREST 431 
 
 other uses. One frequently sees buildings, originally erected for 
 office purposes on a badly chosen site, that have been given over 
 to small manufacturing concerns. A building intended for a fac- 
 tory may serve fairly well as a warehouse. 
 
 The importance of these distinctions lies in the fact that the pos- 
 sibility of alternative uses forms a barrier to the depreciation of the 
 value of the free capital that is found to yield less income in some 
 particular use than was expected by the entrepreneur. If such 
 goods can yield a larger income in some other use, they can be trans- 
 ferred (through a change in the nature of the entrepreneur's busi- 
 ness or through sale or lease to other entrepreneurs) to this more 
 profitable use. Such transfers are continually taking place in 
 actual business. 
 
 Capital and Land. The analysis of the process by which capital is 
 valued opens the way for a consideration of a problem that has been suggested 
 in earlier pages, the reason for the economic distinction between capital 
 and land. Some points of similarity are obvious: land and capital are 
 both valued according to their income-yielding power. The selling value of 
 land, like the selling value of capital, is simply the capitalization of the pro- 
 spective income to be derived from it. From the point of view of the individ- 
 ual investor the purchase of land for productive purposes is an investment 
 of capital just as truly as is the purchase of capital goods. 
 
 Yet there are equally obvious differences : land is given by nature ; capital 
 is "man-made." The amount of land is limited a statement that holds 
 true whether we have in mind the land actually available for productive 
 uses under existing conditions, or whether we have in mind the whole surface 
 of the earth. The supply of capital, on the other hand, is capable of 
 indefinite extension. It may be said, of course, that an extension of 
 transportation facilities, by which the available supply of land is increased, 
 is a " production of land." This is, however, only a figurative use of the 
 word "production." In this figurative sense the growth of a city, by which 
 barren areas become desirable building lots or factory sites, is likewise a 
 " production of land." The recent opening up of the Canadian Northwest 
 has been due to the production of capital in the form of railroads. The 
 land was already there, but the necessary form of capital was lacking. 
 Another distinction is found in the fact that land, in its most essential 
 qualities, is a permanent thing, while capital is of all possible degrees of 
 durability. 
 
 These obvious physical differences between land and capital would hardly 
 justify us in drawing a line between them in a discussion of the distribution 
 of wealth unless these physical differences were the causes of differences in
 
 432 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the ways in which the incomes from land and capital are determined dif- 
 ferences, that is, between rent and interest. Here, again, we find points of 
 similiarity and points of difference. The points of likeness become promi- 
 nent when we view the mechanism of wealth production as it exists at any 
 given time, but become less significant as we shift our view to the forces at 
 work through a considerable period of time. 
 
 If, for example, we could take something like an instantaneous photograph 
 of the processes of the production and distribution of wealth, we would see no 
 important differences between the capital and the land used in production. 
 We would see that society is equipped with a stock of capital goods, in all 
 stages of wear, of all possible degrees of technical efficiency, and varying 
 greatly in fitness or adaptability to the work of producing the particular 
 products that consumers are demanding. Not all of these capital goods are 
 yielding an income that is sufficient to provide for their replacement as they 
 wear out, and in addition to pay a surplus, or premium, in the term of in- 
 terest. Some, it is true, may be yielding even more than the amount neces- 
 sary for these purposes. Machinery of new and exceptionally efficient sorts, 
 but not as yet of widespread or general use; raw materials or dealers' 
 stocks of goods that, by reason of a sudden increase in demand, are selling at 
 an exceptionally high price, such capital goods may be earning consider- 
 ably more than interest and replacement. 
 
 On the other hand, we see a large amount of capital in such forms as obso- 
 lete kinds of machines, ill-planned factory buildings, raw materials or dealers' 
 stocks in trade that were bought in expectation of a demand that did not 
 materialize. Such capital goods may earn considerably less than interest 
 and replacement. When capital is once fixed in definite forms, the question 
 of the original money cost of the capital does not enter into the question of 
 the profitableness of using it. An entrepreneur who borrows money to invest 
 in capital goods has to repay the interest and ultimately the principal of the 
 loan, whether this particular investment of capital proves sufficiently remuner- 
 ative or not. In accounting practice such expenses are called " fixed charges," 
 because they go on whether the capital is used profitably or not. In fact, 
 the entrepreneur will find it to his advantage to use the capital, rather than to 
 let it lie idle, so long as its use adds anything to his total net income. A ma- 
 chine may thus be worth using, even if not worth replacing; dealers can 
 better afford to sell their goods for less than they paid for them than not to sell 
 them at all; a landlord will prefer to rent a building at a very low cost, 
 rather than to let it remain vacant. Capital goods that are just barely worth 
 using may be called "marginal capital goods," and are, from our present 
 viewpoint, analogous to marginal land. At any given time, then, the exist- 
 ing capital goods which it does not pay to use may be thought of as " below 
 the margin," while the income yielded by the better capital goods may be 
 thought of as a rent of capital, analogous in many ways to the rent of land. 
 For this reason Professor Marshall has called the income from capital goods,
 
 INTEREST 433 
 
 when the point of view takes into account only a short period of time, 
 quasi-rent. 
 
 When, however, we shift our point of view so as to take into account a 
 longer period of time, we see an important difference between the income 
 from land and the income from capital. We see, then, that society's stock of 
 capital is a shifting thing. On the one hand, it is being continually depleted 
 on account of the fact that, in the process of production, capital goods are 
 being used up, worn out, or because they are in some cases passing for other 
 reasons below the margin of profitable use. On the other hand, the stock 
 of capital is being continually replenished by the investment of savings in 
 new forms of capital goods. Most of these investments merely replace capi- 
 tal that has been worn out or used up, but some, and in a progressive society, 
 a considerable proportion, represent the creation of new forms of capital. 
 
 Now, as we have seen, the investment of savings in capital goods is guided 
 by the estimates that entrepreneurs make of the profitableness of these invest- 
 ments, the criterion of the profitableness of any possible investment being its 
 ability to replace the principal and provide for the interest on the money 
 invested. When experience has shown that particular forms of capital will 
 not measure up to this standard of profitableness, these forms will not be 
 replaced as they wear out. When certain forms of capital enable entrepre- 
 neurs to get any considerable surplus over and above interest and replacement, 
 the tendency will be, so far as competition rules (that is, so far as monopoly, 
 as in the case of patented machinery, does not prevent), to increase the 
 investments in these forms of capital, and in this way to force the earnings of 
 these specially advantageous forms of capital down to the common level of 
 interest and replacement. Just as the expense of producing consumption 
 goods forms a " normal value," to which their actual prices (under competitive 
 condition) continually tend to approximate, so the expenses incurred in in- 
 vestments of capital form a "normal remuneration of capital," toward which 
 its actual earnings continually tend. Similarly, the value of capital, although 
 actually determined at any one time, like the value of land, by its ability to 
 earn an income for its possessor, tends in the long run to approximate the 
 expense of producing capital. This expense includes, it must be remembered, 
 both the actual money cost of new capital goods and the expense of interest 
 on this money cost. Normal interest is the interest on absolutely free capital 
 in the form of loanable funds. 
 
 Land, of course, has no normal value, because it has no cost of production. 
 This difference is not of mere theoretical importance, but has an important 
 bearing upon many social problems. For example, when we take a long 
 period of time into account, no such thing as an "unearned increment" 
 appears in the value of capital. Moreover, while both rent and interest are 
 alike in the sense that they are payments for productive services, interest is 
 more clearly an earned income than is rent. For productivity has to be 
 imputed to capital because its supply is limited on account of its expenses 
 
 2 F
 
 434 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of production and on account of the sacrifices involved in waiting, while 
 productivity is imputed to the better lands simply because the supply of them 
 is limited by nature. When we measure rent as a return per acre (or other 
 unit) of land, and interest as a percentage on the money invested, we recognize 
 this fundamental distinction between rent and interest. That rent may 
 be viewed for some purposes as interest on the value of the land, and that in- 
 terest (and replacement) may similarly be viewed (at any given time) as a 
 "quasi-rent" of capital goods, does not alter the fundamental nature of the 
 distinction. 
 
 We have seen in another connection that the shifting of investment by 
 which the earnings of capital are made to tend toward a normal standard is 
 easier in the case of the more transient forms of capital than in the case of 
 the more durable forms. The more durable a capital good the more nearly 
 is the income derived from it analogous to the rent of land. As was suggested 
 in the discussion of rent, it is not necessary or advisable to draw a hard and 
 fast line between capital and land. Permanent investments of capital in the 
 form of improvements to land may very properly be regarded as land. The 
 farmer who is contemplating installing a drainage system or an irrigation 
 system for his land views such an investment, at the time, as an investment 
 of capital. But when the capital is definitely incorporated with the land in 
 these permanent forms, there is no reason why it should be called capital 
 rather than land. The total income yielded by the improved acres will, in 
 all essential particulars, be land rent. 
 
 Capital and Consumption Goods. There arc also some points of like- 
 ness between capital and the more durable forms of consumption goods. The 
 person who buys a piano is not only satisfying his present wants, but expects 
 to get from it a long period of use, extending into the future. The purchase 
 of any durable consumption good is in this way one form of saving for the 
 future. Moreover, such provisions for future wants will not be made unless 
 we feel that these future wants are important enough to justify us in giving 
 up some possible present satisfaction. In other words, we will not substitute 
 future utilities for present utilities by the purchase of durable consumption 
 goods unless the future utilities are enough greater than the present utilities 
 to compensate us for the necessary waiting. This compensation for the dif- 
 ference between present satisfactions and future satisfactions is obviously 
 analogous to interest. 
 
 These facts must be taken into account in any full analysis of the valuation 
 of consumption goods, but they do not justify us in obliterating the line be- 
 tween capital and consumption goods. Consumption goods yield directly 
 an income of satisfactions; capital yields a money income, but only in an 
 indirect way does it yield an income of satisfactions. A rented house is not, 
 from the social point of view, capital. It yields a direct income of satisfactions 
 to its occupant ; the fact that the landlord sells the annual use of it instead 
 of selling the permanent property rights in it is a fact of minor significance.
 
 INTEREST 435 
 
 A merchant's stock in trade is capital because it will yield a money income 
 to its possessor ; l when sold to consumers, the same goods become consump- 
 tion goods because they yield an income of satisfactions. In short, the dis- 
 tinction between capital and consumption goods is based upon one of the 
 most fundamental things in the existing economic system the fact that 
 the income which men receive for the productive services of their capital 
 are money incomes. 
 
 Capital and Wages. In many undertakings wages are paid to workmen 
 engaged in the production of goods before the goods are sold. A farmer, 
 for example, has to pay his harvest hands and other workmen before he 
 receives any money from the sale of his wheat. Whether he borrows the 
 amount needed for wages, or whether he pays them out of his own savings, 
 interest on the amount advanced has to be counted among the expenses of 
 production, and the wages advanced are, for the time being, an investment 
 of capital. In most manufacturing establishments a more or less lengthy 
 average period of time elapses between work actually done by the workmen 
 and the sale of the products of their work. In such establishments a con- 
 siderable amount of capital is invested in wage advances. This does not 
 mean that we are to consider the laborers as being in any sense capital. For 
 the gradual process by which the raw material becomes the finished product 
 is itself a continuous investment of capital. All of the various expenses of 
 production are really different ways of investing money in capital goods. 
 Add to the cost of the raw material all of the expenses (including wages and 
 payments of rent and interest as well) incurred in order to produce the 
 finished product of the establishment, and you have simply the total invest- 
 ment in capital goods in the form of the finished product. A complete 
 inventory of capital goods would include then (in addition to buildings, 
 machinery, etc.) not only raw materials and the finished products that are 
 ready for sale to consumers, but also the products on hand at any one time in a 
 partly finished state. Thus, though the payment of wages is often an invest- 
 ment of capital, it must be remembered that the payment of wages is only 
 one of the ways in which money is invested in concrete, definite, capital goods. 
 
 The Rate of Interest. Interest, as the price paid for the serv- 
 ices of capital, is determined by the supply and demand of capital. 
 By this we mean, not the supply and demand of concrete capital 
 goods, a matter which comes under the general laws of price, 2 
 but the supply and demand of the loanable funds, the money 
 capital which is available for investment in concrete capital goods. 
 
 1 The relation of goods to their possessors, rather than to their owners, gives 
 the more satisfactory basis for the distinction between capital goods and corn- 
 sumption goods. The example of the rented house makes this clear. 
 
 a See discussion of the expense and value of capital on page 428.
 
 436 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The demand for capital, as we have seen, is based ultimately on 
 the demand for the products of capital; that is, on the demand for 
 consumption goods. The entrepreneur bases his demand for capi- 
 tal upon his estimate of the demand for his products, together 
 with his estimate of the relative economy of the use of different 
 amounts of capital. In combining labor, capital, and land for 
 productive purposes, he will be guided consciously or unconsciously 
 by the law of diminishing productivity. He has to take into ac- 
 count in this connection both the technical efficiency (that is, the 
 real productive efficiency) and the expense of land, labor, and dif- 
 ferent kinds of capital. This latter consideration means that the 
 interest rate is itself one of the factors determining the demand for 
 capital. The higher '"he rate of interest, the greater will be the 
 expenses of production, and the smaller, in general, will be the de- 
 mand for those goods, in the production of which the use of capital 
 plays an especially important part. Moreover, the higher the in- 
 terest rate, the smaller, other things being equal, will be the rela- 
 tive proportions of capital, and the larger will be the relative pro- 
 portions of labor and land which it will pay entrepreneurs to use. 
 
 As the technical efficiency of capital is increased through 
 the progress of science and invention, the more profitable does 
 its use become. For the demand for it increases not only 
 because the consequent reduction in the prices of goods means 
 larger sales, but also because the use of larger proportions of capi- 
 tal in production becomes advisable. The entrepreneur wants 
 simply the maximum productive efficiency at the least cost. A 
 unit of productive efficiency in the form of capital becomes cheaper, 
 first, as the interest rate decreases, and second, as a given outlay 
 will purchase more efficient forms of capital goods. 
 
 The supply of capital depends ultimately upon the supply of 
 waiting. This, as we have seen in the discussion of the necessity 
 of interest, is something which varies with the interest rate. Other 
 things being equal, the higher the interest rate, the larger will be 
 the parts of money incomes that will be saved rather than spent 
 immediately in the satisfaction of wants. It has sometimes been 
 said that saving increases as wealth increases. If this is taken to 
 mean that the larger the income of the individual, the larger, other
 
 INTEREST 437 
 
 things being equal, will be the amount he will save, the statement 
 probably expresses a general truth. The larger the income, the 
 less important are the immediate wants dependent for their satis- 
 faction on a given amount of money. It does not follow that the 
 proportion of the income that is saved is apt to be any larger in the 
 case of a large income than a small income. If, on the other hand, 
 the statement is taken to refer to the increase of wealth in society 
 at large, we have to take account of the fact that as wealth increases 
 new wants develop, and the net effect on saving is apt to depend 
 on the character of the new wants, whether they call for increased 
 current expenditures or whether they involve the accumulation of 
 considerable sums. Convenient opportunities for saving, such as 
 those afforded by savings banks, insurance companies, and the 
 supply of convenient forms of investment securities have (apart 
 from the rate of interest they offer) an important effect upon the 
 amount of saving. 
 
 Gross Interest and Net Interest. Net interest is pure interest 
 the amount actually necessary to recompense marginal waiting. 
 Gross interest the interest actually paid on loans includes 
 payments for other things. In the first place, actual interest often 
 includes some payment for the supervision which the capitalist 
 has to maintain over his investment. Even the man who "lives 
 on his income" usually has to devote a certain amount of time to 
 the investigation of the safety of different possible investments, to 
 the collection of interest and principal and similar things. The 
 net earnings of a savings bank the difference between the in- 
 terest they get on their investments and the interest they pay their 
 depositors are partly a payment for this element of supervision. 
 
 A second element in gross interest is the payment for the risk 
 the lender undergoes of losing all or part of his expected income 
 (including principal and interest). This does not mean, as some 
 writers have said, that the interest rate contains an element of 
 insurance, for insurance means the elimination of individual risk 
 through the combination of risks. The fact is simply that, as 
 every one knows, lenders will not take greater risks without the 
 prospect of greater gains. There is some element of speculation 
 in all loans but the very safest, and the extra income received on
 
 438 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the more legitimate loans is more akin to speculative profits than 
 to insurance. 
 
 Usury Laws. Interest is one form of price in regard to which 
 society still expresses some distrust of the operation of unhindered 
 competitive forces. Only nine American states do not provide a 
 legal maximum above which the interest rate cannot legally be 
 fixed. Such laws are based on the justifiable assumption that the 
 borrower is in many cases the weaker bargainer, pressed often by 
 that necessity which "never drove a good bargain." In many 
 cases the laws are not enforced, but in other cases they do have an 
 important effect on some kinds of loans, especially bank loans in 
 the rural districts, farm mortgages and overdue book credits. 
 It is to be feared, however, that their result is often not so much 
 to lower the rate of interest as to cut off many loans which lenders 
 would not be justified in making except at high rates of interest. 
 In the case of many loans on fairly good security, however, usury 
 laws have probably operated to the advantage of the borrowers. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Could a socialist state dispense with interest? with waiting? 
 
 2. How has the rate of interest been affected by the opening up of new and 
 fertile lands ? 
 
 3. Use supply and demand curves to illustrate the determination of the 
 rate of interest. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BOHM-BAWERK, E. VON. Capital and Interest; and Positive Theory of 
 
 Capital, Books V-VII. 
 
 CARVER, T. N. The Distribution of Wealth, Chap. VI. 
 CASSELL, G. The Nature and Necessity of Interest. 
 FISHER, IRVING. Capital and Income and The Rate of Interest. 
 GONNER, E. C. K. Interest and Saving. 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 4th ed., Vol. I, Book II, 
 
 Chap. IV; Book IV, Chap. VII; Book V, Chap. IX; Book VI, 
 
 Chap. VI.
 
 CHAPTER XXV 
 PROFITS 
 
 THE difference between the total money income which an en- 
 trepreneur receives and his expenses of production constitutes 
 his profits. Profits, then, are a surplus over and above the expenses 
 of production. There are two ways of measuring profits: first, 
 with reference to some unit of time, such as a year; and, second, 
 with reference to particular units of product. Thus, when a manu- 
 facturer speaks of his profits during a year, he has in mind the 
 difference between his total expenditures and total receipts for 
 that year. But when he speaks of his profits on a particular sale, 
 he has in mind the difference between the expense of producing 
 the particular goods sold and the prices received for them. The 
 two ways of measuring profits are not alike, because a large part 
 of the expenses incurred by an entrepreneur in any given year 
 may be payments for work done in connection with the production 
 of goods that will not be marketed until some later time. In the 
 long run, however, the amount of annual profits will be determined 
 by the profits on particular transactions or on particular products, 
 so that for present purposes it is not necessary to press the dis- 
 tinction any farther. It is sometimes more convenient to use the 
 word " profits " in one sense, and sometimes in the other sense. 
 
 Profits, being a surplus, do not constitute a homogeneous in- 
 come determined by any one principle or set of principles. They 
 are the resultant of all the forces that tend to bring about inequali- 
 ties between the prices paid for things and the expenses of produc- 
 ing them. It is not possible in a brief analysis even to attempt to 
 break up this mixed form of income into all of its constituent 
 parts. Attention may be called, however, to some of the more 
 important and obvious elements in profits. These are: entre- 
 
 439
 
 440 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 preneurs' wages, speculative gains, chance gains, and gains of 
 bargaining. 
 
 Entrepreneur's Wage. This element in profits is sometimes 
 called the " wages of management," and constitutes the payment 
 received by the entrepreneur for his services as manager or super- 
 visor of his business. It is not easy to draw a line between this 
 element in profits and wages. In fact, " entrepreneur's wage " 
 could be discussed just as appropriately under the general head 
 of wages as in connection with the general subject of profits. The 
 only distinguishing things about this particular kind of wages are 
 that, unless the entrepreneur adopts the bookkeeping form of 
 paying wages to himself, they come out of the general surplus or 
 residuum commonly called profits in actual business, and that they 
 are the wages paid for a particular kind of labor. The average 
 American farmer usually does a certain amount of work himself 
 that might be done by hired laborers, and so far as his income 
 represents the amount he saves by doing such work himself, it is 
 to be regarded as ordinary wages. But in addition, he does other 
 work of a more purely managerial quality, including the general 
 direction of the time and methods of tillage and harvesting, the 
 organization of the working force; in fact, the determination of 
 what may be succinctly described as the general coordination of 
 labor, capital, and land. The reader may ask: Could not this 
 part of the work be [turned over to a salaried foreman ? Certainly, 
 and in some cases, as on the estates of so-called " gentlemen 
 farmers," all of it. In fact, the amount of the managerial work 
 actually done by the entrepreneur himself in any kind of under- 
 taking is a variable quantity, depending upon the extent to which 
 managerial authority is delegated to foremen, superintendents, 
 and salaried managers. In any case the " wages of management " 
 exist, although they do not always exist as " entrepreneur's wage," 
 nor do they always constitute a part of profits. 
 
 Even in cases where the entrepreneur is in all respects his own 
 manager (which is, after all, the most frequent case in a host of 
 small business undertakings), the entrepreneur's wage constitutes 
 a kind of minimum profits, and may very properly be added to 
 the real expenses of production. Minimum profits are necessary
 
 PROFITS 441 
 
 profits, the profits needed to induce the entrepreneur to continue 
 his productive work. In many cases they can be measured 
 roughly by the salary which the entrepreneur could get by working 
 for some one else. Some men would prefer to be their own 
 masters even at a smaller income, while others would shrink from 
 the responsibilities of independent business life, even if a larger 
 income were attached to it, so this method of measuring minimum 
 profits is only approximate. 
 
 Minimum profits will vary with managerial efficiency. The 
 more efficient farmer will get a larger product with a given equip- 
 ment of land, labor, and capital than will the less efficient farmer. 1 
 So will the more efficient manufacturer. Managerial efficiency 
 really means productive efficiency, and differences in managerial 
 efficiency will cause corresponding differences in minimum profits. 
 
 Speculative Gains. Modern business, based as it is on ex- 
 change economy, and production " for the market," is of necessity 
 speculative in character, and the entrepreneur is of necessity a 
 speculator. A speculator is a man who buys things in the hope 
 of selling them later at a higher price, or who sells things which 
 he does not own, hoping to buy them at a lower price. The en- 
 trepreneur buys labor, capital, and land, and uses them in the 
 production of things which he hopes to sell for more than the 
 expenses of production. The farmer who decides to devote more 
 land to certain crops and less land to other crops than he did in 
 the preceding year is guided mainly by his estimate of the prices 
 which the different crops will sell for. The merchant purchases 
 his stock according to the best estimates he can make of the kind 
 of goods he will find customers for. Even when goods are sold 
 before they are produced, as when a contracter agrees to build a 
 house for a certain price, the entrepreneur still runs the risk that 
 
 1 It has been suggested that the difference between the product of the better 
 farmers and of the poorer farmers is not only absolutely but relatively greater in 
 the case of good land than in the case of poor lands. If this is so, it helps to ex- 
 plain the observed fact that the best farmers generally have the best lands. That 
 is, they would be able to pay a higher rent or a higher price for the good lands than 
 the poor farmers could. In this case some of the higher efficiency of the better 
 farmers might result in higher rents rather than higher profits. (See Taylor, 
 Agricultural Economics, Chap. IX.)
 
 442 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 his expenses of production will be greater than the price agreed 
 upon. If he attempts to eliminate the element of uncertainty 
 by contracting for his materials in advance, he simply shifts some 
 of the risk to lumber dealers, hardware merchants, etc., while he 
 himself still assumes some risk, although of a different kind. 
 That is, he guards himself against possible loss, but by the same 
 process he gives up the chance of the higher profits he would have 
 got for himself if the prices of materials had been lower at the 
 actual time of construction than they were when he made the 
 contract. 
 
 This element of risk taking is the very essence of modern busi- 
 ness, and the most successful entrepreneurs are, in general, 
 those who are the most successful risk takers. Risk taking, in 
 this sense, does not mean a blind dependence upon chance. If 
 this were so, there would be no reason why business failure should 
 not be about as common as business success. Risk taking is 
 nearly synonymous with business enterprise. It involves careful 
 estimates of the amounts of product that can be got from different 
 combinations of labor, capital, and land, and equally careful 
 estimates of the salability of such products. It is in this latter 
 field, which involves the diagnosis of market conditions with a 
 view to ascertaining their probable trend, that the entrepreneur's 
 skill finds its chief opportunity. This kind of skill means knowl- 
 edge and foresight very different things from mere willingness 
 to " take a chance." Yet, though the efficient entrepreneur deals 
 with probabilities rather than possibilities in his estimates, he is 
 nevertheless a risk taker, a speculator, for his estimates have to 
 do with market conditions that are beyond his personal control. 
 While his success may be probable, it is very far from being 
 certain. 
 
 The functions of the entrepreneur as a risk taker are clearly 
 distinguishable from his functions as a manager. Managerial 
 efficiency, as we have seen, is the ability to combine and direct 
 labor, capital, and land in such a way as to get the maximum prod- 
 uct. Risk-taking efficiency means the ability to get the largest 
 receipts from a given expenditure. When we speak of managerial 
 efficiency, we have especially in mind the technical side of produc-
 
 PROFITS 
 
 443 
 
 tion the manner in which the factors in production are utilized; 
 risk-taking efficiency refers to the value side of production the 
 way in which the use of capital, labor, and land is directed into 
 the most remunerative channels. Managerial duties may be dele- 
 gated to salaried employees; the risk-taking function is one which 
 the entrepreneur cannot shift to another. 1 
 
 This part of competitive profits is in its very nature a shifting 
 and even transient thing. To anticipate consumers' demands 
 correctly is not in itself a guarantee of profits to any entrepreneur. 
 If other entrepreneurs have counted on the same demand, it may 
 easily happen that the total product cannot be sold at a profitable 
 price. In fact, the " market conditions " which the entrepreneur 
 has to forecast include the conditions of supply as well as of de- 
 mand. But even in case a given entrepreneur has succeeded in 
 producing the precise things that consumers are demanding and 
 that other entrepreneurs are not producing, and has thus been able 
 to get large profits, he cannot count on their permanence. De- 
 mand may change, but even if demand remains constant or in- 
 creases, his large profits will be a standing invitation to other 
 entrepreneurs to enter the same field a condition which will 
 continue until competition forces the profits of this particular 
 kind of business down to where they just suffice to pay the wages 
 of management. If profits in any establishment or any industry 
 go below this minimum point, the tendency will be for entrepre- 
 neurs to shift their investments to more profitable undertakings. 
 
 The kind of profits which we are now discussing constitute the 
 guiding principle, the incentive, in modern economic life. It is 
 the desire to get money profits that leads entrepreneurs to produce 
 particular things and to produce them in particular ways. It is 
 for this reason that old channels of productive effort are con- 
 tinually being abandoned and that the use of labor, capital, and 
 land is continually being guided into new channels. The shifting 
 
 1 This statement may seem open to the qualification implied in the fact that in 
 some cases the foresight and skill utilized are those of employees (the " buyers " 
 for a large retail store, for example). Yet while the entrepreneur may thus depend 
 in part upon others' knowledge of market conditions, the risk involved is neces- 
 sarily assumed by himself.
 
 444 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of productive effort which the pursuit of money profits involves 
 consists, for the most part, of efforts on the part of entrepreneurs 
 to meet the shifting wants of consumers. 
 
 One of the strongest arguments for the superiority of the competi- 
 tive system over any possible substitute for it lies in the fact that, 
 under competition, the guiding of production into the channels 
 indicated by the search for money profits will result in the maxi- 
 mum satisfaction of human wants. This follows from the fact 
 that the prices people are willing to pay for certain commodities 
 measure the importance which they attach to the possession of 
 those commodities. The shifting of labor and capital from less 
 profitable to more profitable uses means, in general, that more 
 intense wants will be satisfied with the same expenditure of pro- 
 ductive energy. All this is implied in the statement made above 
 that the shifting of productive effort is mainly in response to the 
 shifting wants of consumers. This argument, that under free 
 competition the pursuit of money profits leads to the best adapta- 
 tion of productive efforts to the satisfaction of the wants of con- 
 sumers, is one that has rarely been met squarely by those who 
 attack the competitive system. There are, however, several im- 
 portant considerations that lessen to some extent its force. 
 
 In the first place, the extent to which the wants of any individual 
 affect the ordering of the productive processes depends upon his 
 purchasing power, that is, primarily, upon his income. It is mani- 
 festly absurd to say that the shifting of labor and capital from the 
 production of necessities for the poor to the production of luxuries 
 for the rich, simply because it may be more profitable, necessarily 
 means a better satisfaction of human wants. The extent to which 
 wants are satisfied depends on the way wealth is distributed as 
 well as upon the amount and kinds of things produced. 
 
 Moreover, even granting that the stimulus of money profits 
 leads to the best practicable satisfaction of the wants of present 
 consumers, this may sometimes be achieved by imposing added 
 difficulties in want-satisfaction on future generations. The lines 
 of procedure that will bring maximum profits to entrepreneurs 
 sometimes run counter to the more permanent interests of society. 
 We all recognize, for example, that there may be such a thing as a
 
 PROFITS 
 
 445 
 
 too rapid exploitation of natural resources. The history of timber 
 lands in America furnishes an instructive example. 
 
 A still more important qualification of the statement that com- 
 petitive profit seeking works for the best interests of society, 
 viewed as a body of consumers, is found in the fact that when we 
 begin to speak of the interests of society, we introduce, of necessity, 
 the ethical point of view. This means that we must consider not 
 only the quantity, but also the quality of want-satisfactions. For 
 purposes of the economic analysis of market forces, we make no 
 distinction between different kinds of utilities, but it is impossible 
 to discuss social well-being without taking into account the fact 
 that from the point of view of the interests of society some kinds 
 of " utilities " are good and some are bad, and that even the better 
 kinds of want-satisfactions vary greatly in their importance, when 
 measured by any criterion of social welfare. The production of 
 socially undesirable things, such as intoxicating liquors, adulterated 
 foods, ill-ventilated tenements, etc., is often prohibited, while, on 
 the other hand, society has found that certain socially desirable 
 things, such as schools, parks, libraries, clean streets, etc., 
 will not be supplied at all, or will not be supplied in sufficient 
 quantities by private business enterprise. All indications point to 
 a very considerable extension of organized social activity at pre- 
 cisely those points where the private pursuit of money profits 
 has proven itself inadequate. 
 
 Chance Gains. It often happens that an entrepreneur is able 
 to get profits on account of some unforeseen and purely fortuitous 
 circumstances. Such profits should not be confused with the 
 kind that have just been discussed, which vary with the foresight 
 and enterprise of the entrepreneur. Capricious changes in fashion 
 often bring temporarily high profits to dealers who happen to have 
 the right kinds of goods in stock, or to manufacturers who happen 
 to have the equipment needed to produce the right kinds of goods. 
 American farmers have profited at different times by the failure of 
 the European grain crop. Other examples will suggest themselves to 
 the reader. There are chance losses as well as chance gains, and 
 they are probably quite as numerous and important. Chance 
 gains, therefore, do not constitute any important part of the income
 
 446 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 going to entrepreneurs as a class, but they are often a considerable 
 element in the profits of particular entrepreneurs. 
 
 Gains of Bargaining. We have seen in other connections that 
 the prices of commodities and services are in many cases fixed only 
 loosely by the forces of supply and demand. In the actual process 
 of bargaining, the shrewder party to the bargain may very often sell 
 for more than his minimum selling price, or buy for less than his 
 maximum buying price. Skillful bargaining swells the entrepreneur's 
 profits, first, by increasing the prices he gets for things, and second, 
 by decreasing his expenses of production. We have seen that in 
 bargaining with an individual laborer the entrepreneur usually 
 has an advantage that tends to increase profits at the expense 
 of wages an advantage which is at least partly lost when the 
 laborers resort to collective bargaining. In bargaining for the use 
 of capital funds, the entrepreneur is apt to know what the loan 
 is worth to him better than the lender does; but, on the other hand, 
 it often happens that the entrepreneur is put at a disadvantage 
 when the loan is a matter of necessity to him, but relatively a matter 
 of indifference to the lender. 
 
 Non- competitive Profits. All of the sources of profits men- 
 tioned above are based on circumstances which arise in the course 
 of ordinary competitive business. In any particular case their 
 magnitude depends on the managing ability, foresight, bargain- 
 ing skill, or good fortune of the entrepreneur. Moreover, of the 
 tendency of competition to eliminate all but minimum profits, 
 the continuance of surplus profits is only achieved, in general, 
 by continued endeavor on the part of the entrepreneur. In the 
 case of monopoly, however, the existence of profits rests upon a 
 very different ground the ability of the monopolist to control 
 the supply. This results normally, as we have seen, in a fixing 
 of monopoly price at the point that will yield the largest net profits. 
 Monopoly profits are not only apt to be higher than competitive 
 profits, but they are also apt to be more stable and permanent in 
 character. 
 
 It very often happens in non-monopolistic undertakings that the 
 entrepreneur who has developed his business to a profitable point 
 is able to attach some degree of permanency to his profits. A
 
 PROFITS 447 
 
 merchant often relies to a very large extent upon the patronage 
 of an established clientele of customers, and in turn he may prefer, 
 other things being equal, to purchase his goods from particular 
 wholesale houses. When a business undertaking is sold as a 
 whole, its established connections of this sort enter into the deter- 
 mination of the price paid for it, under the head of " good-will." 
 This " good-will " element is generally measured by the difference 
 between the valuation of a business establishment and the valua- 
 tion of the specific assets (minus the specific liabilities) of the 
 business. In the sale of a newspaper it often happens that the 
 " good-will " of the enterprise (its established advertising and 
 subscription patronage) is the only thing actually transferred by 
 one entrepreneur to the other. Those more or less definitely 
 established kinds of profits which give rise to " good -will " values 
 must not be confused with monopoly profits. Monopoly implies 
 the absence of competition. " Good-will " profits are to be attrib- 
 uted rather to the imperfect working of competition, to the eco- 
 nomic inertia and friction which result from the fact that buyers 
 are guided to a very large extent by custom and habit rather than 
 by conscious choice. Moreover, in many small transactions, for cus- 
 tomers to attempt to buy always at the lowest price would result 
 in a waste of time and energy disproportionate to the gain. Hence, 
 aside from the influence of custom and habit, there may often be 
 rational ground for the continued patronage of particular establish- 
 ments which customers have found to be trustworthy. 
 
 " Good-will " is, in general, of most importance in retail estab- 
 lishments, where annual profits are apt to be made up of the specific 
 profits on a large number of relatively small transactions. In 
 the larger transactions of wholesale, jobbing, and manufacturing 
 establishments, the element of " good -will " is not entirely absent, 
 but the vigilance of expert buyers and the mere size of the ordinary 
 transaction (making even small differences in prices important) 
 tend to reduce it to a minimum. A noteworthy feature of modern 
 business, however, is the attempt on the part of manufacturers 
 and wholesalers to influence the demand of the ultimate consumers 
 of their products through the use of advertising. The trade-mark 
 privilege, which enables particular brands of competitively pro-
 
 448 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 duced goods to be distinguished, is an important factor in the efforts 
 of such producers to gain and hold the patronage of the ultimate 
 consumers. The " good-will " of a large manufacturing establish- 
 ment thus comes to be in some cases as valuable a possession as 
 a monopoly franchise. Farmers, and other producers of standard 
 kinds and classes of goods, have small opportunity to acquire 
 " good -will " profits. 
 
 The Social Dividend. The significance of the statement made 
 in an earlier chapter, that the distribution of wealth is a matter 
 of valuation, should now be clear to the reader. But since the 
 detailed character of the analysis may make a broad and inclusive 
 view of this valuation process somewhat difficult, it will be worth 
 our while to bring together the more important conclusions we 
 have reached, and to try to see them from a somewhat different 
 point of view. 
 
 The social dividend is made up of the scarce and valuable things (com- 
 modities and services) that are of direct use in the satisfaction of human wants. 
 The process by which the claims of different individuals against the social 
 dividend are adjudicated is the process of the distribution of wealth. We 
 have seen that these claims rest upon various grounds. Some men give of 
 their own time and energy to the production of goods. Others permit the 
 use of the scarce and valuable natural agents (especially land) which they 
 own. Still others exchange part of their present claims against the social 
 dividend for future claims, thereby permitting part of the productive work 
 of society to be turned toward the creation of indirect goods, the use of which 
 operates, in the long run, to greatly increase the social dividend. 
 
 A unifying characteristic of these three different kinds of claims is the fact 
 that the wages of labor, the rent of land, and the interest on capital are simply 
 different forms of money income, paid for the services of land, labor, and 
 capital in the production of valuable things. The valuations which society 
 puts on the productive services of its members or of their productive goods 
 are determined through the activities of entrepreneurs. 
 
 The relation of the activities of entrepreneurs to the money incomes of the 
 members of society is twofold. On the one hand, the purchasing power of 
 consumers is derived from their money incomes, which in this way constitute 
 the means by which the demand for the entrepreneur's products expresses 
 itself. On the other hand, the money incomes received by laborers and by 
 those who supply capital and land are paid by entrepreneurs in return for pro- 
 ductive services. The wages, rent, and interest expended by any one entre- 
 preneur for these productive services are in turn paid over by the individuals 
 who receive them to other entrepreneurs in return for their products. There
 
 PROFITS 449 
 
 is thus a continuous flow of money income through the hands of entrepre- 
 neurs, appearing first in the form of the prices that are paid for an entre- 
 preneur's goods, then emerging in the form of the rent, wages, and interest 
 that the entrepreneur pays for the service of the factors in production, then 
 reappearing in the prices paid for other goods, and so on in a continually 
 recurring cycle of income and outgo. 1 
 
 This process is made more complicated, however, by the fact that not all of 
 the entrepreneur's expenses appear directly as rent, wages, or interest. A con- 
 siderable part, and in many cases (as in mercantile establishments), the largest 
 part of such expenditures are for various concrete forms of capital, raw 
 materials, dealers' stocks of goods, machines, and the like. Here a part of 
 the money income received by the entrepreneur in the form of the prices paid 
 for his own goods emerges in the prices which he pays for the goods sold by 
 other entrepreneurs, and which, in turn, make up a part of their money in- 
 comes. But this other class of entrepreneurs who supply capital goods 
 rather than consumption goods are subject to the same necessity of ex- 
 pending their money incomes in the payment of wages, rent, and interest, 
 and in the purchase of different kinds of capital goods. To push the analysis 
 still further would obviously lead us only into needless repetition. One 
 important fact, however, appears clearly : If we could trace the expense of 
 producing any consumption good back through all the long series of services 
 and of production goods that have contributed to its making we would find 
 that this expense reduces itself, ultimately, to rent, wages, and interest, 
 not counting what remains in the entrepreneur's hands as profits. Part 
 of the "flow of money income" passes through the hands of a chain of 
 entrepreneurs, but it nevertheless originates in the prices that consumers 
 pay for the things that satisfy their wants and emerges in the form of the pay- 
 ments made for the productive services of land, labor, and capital. 
 
 Yet another correction must be made, however, to fit this picture of part 
 of the economic process more closely to the facts. The money which con- 
 sumers pay for particular commodities does not usually constitute the actual 
 fund with which the entrepreneur pays for the labor, the land, and the capital 
 goods used in the production of those commodities. Still less does it con- 
 stitute the actual fund from which the entrepreneurs who supply the neces- 
 sary capital goods pay their expenses, or from which the expenses of still 
 more remote stages in the process of production are paid. The roundabout, 
 indirect methods which characterize modern production, and which in- 
 volve the division of the productive process among countless different under- 
 takings, take time. The goods which consumers buy to-day are the result of 
 a long series of productive efforts extending back indefinitely into the past. 
 Similarly the productive efforts of to-day avail but relatively little toward the 
 
 1 To a very large extent, this "flow of money income" does not take the form 
 of the actual circulation of concrete forms of money. For the most part it takes 
 place through the creation and cancellation of credit obligations. 
 2 G
 
 450 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 satisfaction of present wants, for they are in large part directed to forwarding, 
 often in the most indirect ways, the production of things that will come to a 
 final fruition in the satisfaction of human wants only in the more or less re- 
 mote future. 
 
 Viewed in this way the annual product of society is something very different 
 from the social dividend. The year's work is begun with an equipment of 
 economic goods of all kinds, finished goods in the hands of dealers and 
 manufacturers, goods in all stages of completion, growing crops, factory and 
 mercantile buildings, machines, and all the auxiliary apparatus of production 
 in a finished or unfinished state. The annual product includes all the ad- 
 ditions made to this stock of goods, and all that is accomplished in forwarding 
 such goods as are destined for human consumption towards the form, place, 
 and time in which and at which they are wanted. It includes all that is 
 done in a similar way to forward, replenish, and increase the stock of pro- 
 duction goods. It includes also all the personal services that command a 
 money payment which are not embodied in concrete goods, but which con- 
 fer their benefits in the very instance of their performance. 
 
 But while the productive efforts of society are thus constantly building up 
 and modifying the stock of economic goods, this stock is continually being 
 depleted in various ways. The instruments of production are constantly 
 wearing out, or are being cast aside on account of the introduction of either 
 more efficient appliances or more efficient methods which utilize other kinds 
 of appliances. Then, too, as the final outcome of this productive process 
 there is a constant stream of finished consumption goods passing into the 
 hands of consumers. The social dividend consists of this flow of consumption 
 goods, together with those direct personal services which do not have to do 
 directly or indirectly with the fitting of goods for human consumption, but 
 which nevertheless satisfy wants and command a money payment. While 
 the social dividend is to a large extent the outcome of past work and effort, 
 the annual product is very largely a provision for future wants. 
 
 What is the effect of all these considerations upon our analysis of the flow 
 of money income? It still remains true that the money which consumers 
 pay to entrepreneurs is in turn used by them in the payment of their expenses 
 of production, and that the money which they in turn pay to other entrepre- 
 neurs for various forms of capital goods are used in the payment of expenses 
 of production. But the prices consumers are paying are for goods, the ex- 
 penses of producing which have (at least in greater part) already been paid, 
 and some of them (such as the prices paid for some kinds of capital instru- 
 ments) may have been paid some considerable period of time back in the 
 past. If in turn we should trace back the expenses of producing the capital 
 goods used in producing these consumption goods our search would lead us 
 into the more remote past, while still further analysis of the expenses of pro- 
 duction would discover an increasing number of ramifications running back 
 into the still more distant past. The present flow of money income, original
 
 PROFITS 451 
 
 ing in the prices paid by consumers, passes, as we have seen, through the 
 hands of a chain of entrepreneurs and in this process gets ultimately into the 
 hands of laborers, capitalists, and landlords. But most of the productive 
 services which are thus remunerated are services which will avail toward the 
 satisfaction of future rather than of present wants. In other words, the 
 prices paid for consumers' shares in the social dividend constitute (save for 
 an important exception to be noted presently) the fund which pays for the 
 annual product. The productive efforts of the past, which satisfy the wants 
 of to-day, were paid for out of past income, while the present work of producing 
 goods that will be ripe for consumption only in the future is paid for out of 
 present income. In this fact lies the explanation of the nature and necessity 
 of one of the various kinds of claims against the social dividend interest. 
 
 The outlays which entrepreneurs make in producing goods, so far as 
 they are paid before they receive an income from the sale of the goods, 
 are commonly called investments of capital. Not only, as we have seen, 
 does the entrepreneur invest capital in production goods such as machines 
 and buildings, but his purchases of raw materials, his advances of wages 
 to laborers, the interest which he pays on borrowed capital, and the rent or 
 the purchase price which he pays for land, are usually investments of capi- 
 tal. No such investments can be regarded as remunerative unless the 
 entrepreneur gets in the selling prices of his products enough to provide 
 interest upon such outlays as well as to cover the outlays themselves. 
 These facts were noted in connection with the discussion of interest in an 
 earlier chapter, but there, for simplicity's sake, the analysis was confined to 
 the capital expenditures of the individual entrepreneur. The full signifi- 
 cance of the r61e which capital plays in production does not appear until 
 we view the activities of the individual entrepreneur as only a link in the 
 continuous chain of activities that make up the productive process. 
 
 The point of special significance in this connection is the fact that the 
 finished products sold by some entrepreneurs constitute the capital goods 
 (raw materials, productive appliances, etc.) bought by other entrepreneurs. 
 When one entrepreneur sells his products to another entrepreneur his period 
 of "waiting" is completed, so far as his advances of capital funds in the pro- 
 duction of these particular units of goods are concerned. But the "waiting" 
 is only transferred to the other entrepreneur, who adds further expenditures 
 of capital and, in turn, gets his remuneration from the sale of his product. 
 The important conclusion to which this analysis leads is that (so far as the 
 entrepreneurs have been accurate in their estimates) the prices which con- 
 sumers are paying to-day for finished goods cover not only all the actual money 
 expenditures which have been made in the past in the production of these 
 goods, but also the interest on all such expenditures from the time they were 
 made up to the time of the sale of the finished goods to the ultimate consumer. 
 
 Similarly the expenditures made by entrepreneurs to-day in the production 
 of goods that will directly or indirectly satisfy future wants will (so far as
 
 452 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 these entrepreneurs and those who will control the remaining steps in the 
 productive process are accurate in their estimates) be covered, together 
 with accrued interest, by the prices which consumers will pay in the future. 
 Present wants are satisfied by means of the productive efforts of the past. 
 These productive efforts were paid for out of past income, but the outlays 
 were made in the expectation that present prices would suffice to repay them, 
 with interest. A particular entrepreneur may be interested only in disposing 
 of his products at remunerative prices to the entrepreneurs who stand next 
 to him in the productive series, but this does not alter the essential nature of 
 capital investment, which, from the social point of view, is a cumulative pro- 
 cess. 
 
 The flow of money income which originates in the prices consumers pay 
 to the entrepreneurs with whom they deal emerges in the form of capital 
 expenditures, and so far as these take the form of the purchase of capita) 
 goods they constitute the fund from which other capital expenditures are 
 made by other entrepreneurs. The gross money income of entrepreneurs, 
 then, furnishes by far the most important part of the current supply of capital 
 funds, and the most important form of capital investment is the entrepreneur's 
 customary practice of "putting money back into the business." That this 
 way of investing capital is customary, even habitual, does not mean that the 
 amount as well as the particular forms of such investments is not a matter 
 subject to the discretion of the entrepreneur. So far as the entrepreneur 
 is not hampered by contracts (with customers, other entrepreneurs, money 
 lenders, landlords, or laborers) he is free to do as he pleases with his income. 
 As a matter of fact he is apt to devote a fairly constant proportion of it to the 
 replacement of the capital goods that are being used up or worn out and to the 
 other necessary expenses of continued production. 
 
 It rarely happens, however, in any undertaking, that income and ex- 
 penditure are so nicely adjusted and so evenly distributed through the year 
 that the one always suffices to provide for the other. A temporary surplus 
 may be followed by a temporary deficit. Transfers of goods on credit smooth 
 over some of these irregularities, while the institution of banking provides 
 a mechanism whereby the temporary surpluses of some entrepreneurs 
 are made use of in meeting the temporary deficits of others. Moreover, 
 while the entrepreneur need not continue to renew his capital investments 
 unless he chooses, he is at liberty to do even more than this if he deems it 
 advisable. That is, his profits the excess of his gross income over and 
 above his current and normal capital expenditures may be used for ad- 
 ditional capital expenditures. 
 
 Still another source of capital funds is found in the rent, wages, and interest 
 into which, as we have seen, the expenses of production ultimately resolve 
 themselves. For so far as these forms of income are saved, rather than ex- 
 pended immediately for consumption goods, they may be loaned directly 
 or through savings institutions to entrepreneurs for productive employment.
 
 PROFITS 453 
 
 This is the important exception, previously mentioned, to the statement 
 that " the prices paid for consumers' shares in the social dividend constitute 
 the fund which pays for the annual product." The truth is that as the flow 
 of money income passes from entrepreneur to entrepreneur, a part only, 
 although the larger part, is put into productive expenditures. The residuum 
 is used by entrepreneurs in paying for their own shares in the social dividend. 
 In much the same way the money incomes received by those who furnish 
 labor, land, or capital is only in part paid back to entrepreneurs in return for 
 consumption goods, the residuum being put (through loans to entrepreneurs) 
 into productive expenditures. 
 
 It will be seen, then, that as the flow of money income passes through the 
 hands of entrepreneurs, laborers, capitalists, and landowners, it is divided 
 into two streams, one of which goes to pay for the present goods that have 
 been produced in the past, while the other goes to pay for the present expenses 
 of forwarding the production of goods for future consumption. This division 
 represents a kind of social balancing of possible present satisfactions over 
 against the larger future satisfactions which the productive use of capital 
 makes possible. On the one hand we have the entrepreneurs' estimates of 
 how much specific amounts of capital funds are worth to them, estimates 
 which involve judgments as to the amount of product dependent upon the 
 use of these specific amounts of capital funds, the prices that can be got for 
 such products, and the period of time that will elapse before they will be re- 
 munerated for such investments. On the other hand we have the estimates 
 of those who supply capital funds as to the relative importance of future 
 and present wants. The interest rate will normally be fixed, of course, 
 at a point where the supply and demand of money capital will be in equi- 
 librium. 
 
 In dividing his capital expenses between labor, land, and capital goods 
 the entrepreneur will again be influenced by his estimates of how much the 
 use of specific quantities of each of these factors in production will add to his 
 money income. Here he has to reckon with the fact of diminishing produc- 
 tivity. He can get the same amount of product from different combinations 
 of land, capital goods, and labor, but the larger the proportion of his expendi- 
 tures he devotes to any one of these things (labor, for example), the smaller 
 will be the increment of product dependent upon any one unit of it (any one 
 laborer, for example). The most economical combination of labor, capital 
 goods, and land is reached, of course, when the marginal expenditures for 
 each add equal quantities to his product. All this, however, was discussed 
 in detail when the activities of the individual entrepreneur were taken as 
 the point of departure for the analysis of distribution in an earlier chapter. 
 When we take the social point of view, so that production is made to appear 
 as a cumulative process of capital investment, the expenses for capital goods 
 become reduced to the more fundamental expenditures of rent, wages, and 
 interest, involved in the production of such goods. In this view capital goods
 
 454 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 might, by a legitimate figure of speech, be said to be embodied rent, wages, 
 and interest. 
 
 The social process of production involves the expenditure of rent, wages, 
 and interest for returns of all possible degrees of futurity, and a consequent 
 comparison and balancing of the productivity of investments for shorter and 
 longer periods of time. That is, social estimates of productivity are estimates 
 of the value of the amounts of the ultimate products, realizable at different 
 periods of time in the future, that are dependent upon specific present ex- 
 penditures in the form of rent, wages, or interest. Or, in other words, 
 there is a continuous effort to make the most profitable of all the various 
 possible combinations of land, labor, and waiting. For just as rent, wages, 
 and interest are the ultimate expenses of production, so the ultimate factors 
 in production may be said to be land, labor, and waiting. 
 
 The money incomes which individual laborers, landlords, and capitalists 
 receive, and which constitute the claims (or, more accurately, the potential 
 claims) against the social dividend, are determined by this social estimate of 
 the specific amounts which they add to the value of the annual product, or, 
 ultimately, to the value of finished products. Here again, on account of 
 the law of diminishing productivity, the marginal product of land, labor, or 
 waiting is the measure of the specific product attributed to a unit of land, 
 labor, or waiting. 
 
 It must be remembered, however, that marginal productivity does not 
 depend alone on the technical efficiency of labor, the fertility and accessi- 
 bility of land, and the greater technical or physical productivity of the 
 roundabout, indirect methods which waiting makes possible. 1 It also 
 depends, just as fundamentally, upon the amount and elasticity of the supply 
 of land, labor, and waiting. It has been shown in earlier chapters that the 
 conditions of supply are very different in the case of each of the three factors 
 in production. No account of the distributive process can be complete that 
 does not lay special stress on these differences, for these are the things that 
 become of most importance when economic theory is utilized in the untan- 
 gling of the practical social problems growing out of the distribution of wealth. 
 
 Moreover, we cannot insist too strongly that the statement of the tendency 
 toward an equality of the specific product attributable to a unit of land, 
 labor, or capital funds and the price paid for its use is, after all, only an 
 illuminating way of stating the real problem of distribution. Just as marginal 
 
 1 Whether roundabout, indirect methods of production are inherently more 
 efficient (that is, whether they necessarily yield a larger product with the use of 
 a given amount of labor and land) has been recently a matter of debate among 
 economic writers. The fact that a process is roundabout does not in itself make 
 it more economical. But that many roundabout processes are economical is proved 
 by the simple fact that entrepreneurs find it profitable to use them. This fact 
 is all that is needed to establish the importance of the greater technical produc- 
 tivity of indirect, time using methods of production for the theory of interest.
 
 PROFITS 455 
 
 utility is at the same time the cause and effect of price, so marginal produc- 
 tivity is at the same time the cause and effect of wages, rent, and interest. 
 From one point of view it is seen that the competition of producers makes 
 it necessary that specific units of land, labor, and capital should get a reward 
 proportionate to the value of the amounts which they contribute to the social 
 dividend; from another point of view it is equally clear that the necessary 
 expenditures for land, labor, and capital are, in the long run, potent factors 
 in determining the value of the things that make up the social dividend. 
 
 Furthermore, we are apt to forget that the word "productivity" as used in 
 economics (and generally in current discussions of economic topics) has a 
 distinctly limited meaning. To digress for a moment in order to make the 
 point clearer : In the theory of consumption we emphasize the fact that 
 many of the most important human wants are satisfied by "free goods," 
 which, simply because they are free, lie outside the proper field of economic * 
 investigation. But the enjoyment of these free goods is usually dependent 
 upon the possession of economic goods. Air is a free good, to any one 
 who can demand the economic goods necessary to life. The glorious scenery 
 of the Alps is a free good, to any one who can afford traveling expenses 
 and hotel bills. In general, the enjoyment of many of the finer pleasures 
 of life, involved in the common human relations of an individual to his physical 
 and social environment, are "free," but free only to the individual who can 
 afford the leisure and the economic goods without which many of these 
 "free" pleasures are impossible. 
 
 For present purposes, however, the important point is that there are free 
 production goods as well as free consumption goods. Nature furnishes some 
 of these. The oceans and lakes furnish free pathways for commerce ; natural 
 forces of all kinds are freely utilized by men in the work of production. As 
 was pointed out in an earlier chapter, we do not call these things productive, 
 because no part of the annual product is dependent on the utilization of any 
 particular unit of them. In this technical sense the wind is not productive, 
 but win dmills are. In order to utilize the ocean we have to invest capital 
 in vessels and docks. We have to impute productivity to these things be- 
 cause they will not be furnished unless it is estimated that they will yield a 
 remunerative income, and because the annual product will obviously be 
 reduced if they are not furnished. But we would have to impute productivity 
 to the Strait of Gibraltar if England were able to charge a toll for its use ! 
 
 Somewhat analogous to these "free productive goods" is society's fund 
 of accumulated knowledge of productive methods, the heritage of centuries " 
 of economic evolution. This accumulated industrial experience is an in- 
 finitely more precious possession than the existing store of productive goods. 
 Compare the productive possibilities of a community of men possessing this 
 knowledge, but forced to begin work absolutely without a ready-made stock 
 of capital goods, with those of a tribe of savages suddenly and miraculously 
 equipped with all the productive appliances of modern civilization. Yet this
 
 456 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 vast fund of productive knowledge, so far as it is common property, is not 
 thought of as "productive." The social dividend is continually being in- 
 creased as a result of the discovery of new natural forces, or new ways of 
 harnessing and utilizing natural forces. Secrecy or government patents make 
 it possible for those who first introduce these new methods of production to 
 reap an income from the temporary advantage it gives to them as producers. 
 For the time being these new methods themselves have to be regarded as 
 "productive," although they contribute much more to the increase of the 
 social dividend after they have become matters of common knowledge and 
 use, and hence have ceased to be called " productive." * Disinterested scien- 
 tists, especially those in the employment of the government or of universities, 
 have often given the results of their improvements in industrial methods 
 freely to the world, thereby swelling the social dividend, but not reaping 
 for themselves the pecuniary reward which goes to those who patent their 
 improvements and thereby render them "productive." Moreover, many of 
 the world's greatest advances in the technique of production have been 
 made possible only by the patient researches of investigators in the " unpro- 
 ductive" field of pure science, working solely for love of the work, and with- 
 out hope of pecuniary reward. 2 
 
 We impute productivity, in the technical economic sense, only to goods or 
 services which are the objects of property rights or of analogous rights of con- 
 trol, such as a man's power to dispose of his own labor. The fact is that 
 just as the benefits of free consumption goods are bound up with the posses- 
 sion of larger or smaller quantities of economic goods, so the utilization of 
 free productive agencies is possible only in combination with labor, waiting, 
 and scarce and appropriable natural objects, and these have to be paid for. 
 We harness natural forces for the work of production, but we impute prod- 
 uctivity only to the harness. We continually learn better and better methods 
 of doing our productive work, but we impute productivity only to the ex- 
 penses involved in utilizing these methods, not to the methods themselves. 
 
 It is important that the reader should see the truth in the statement that 
 the laborer, the landlord, and the capitalist get paid in proportion to their 
 respective products. It is equally important that he should see clearly that 
 there are definite limitations to the meaning and significance of the statement. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 i. Is there a sense in which speculative profits can be said to be a reward 
 for productive services? If so, should they be counted among the expenses 
 of production? 
 
 1 The discussion of the social dividend in the preceding page relates only to 
 " normal " or purely competitive production and distribution, and no account 
 has been taken of the "productivity" of monopoly rights. 
 
 * See a note on this point in Merz, History of European Thought in the Nine- 
 teenth Century, Vol. I, p. 92. The list there given could be greatly extended.
 
 PROFITS 
 
 457 
 
 2. Is good- will capital? 
 
 3. Analyze the effect of an increase of expenditures for present goods upon 
 present and future social dividends. 
 
 4. If money wages could be suddenly increased 10 per cent would there 
 be a corresponding increase in real wages ? 
 
 5. Monopolists sometimes curtail their output in order to increase its 
 total value. Should this be called productive? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 CARVER, T. N. Distribution of Wealth, Chap. VII. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 4th ed., Book VI, Chaps. 
 
 VII and VIII. 
 
 HAWLEY, F. B. Enterprise and tfte Productive Process. 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Wages and Capital, especially Chap. III. 
 VEBLEN, THORSTEIN. Theory of Business Enterprise, Chap. III.
 
 PART VI 
 THE RELATION OF THE STATE TO INDUSTRY 
 
 CHAPTER XXVI 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 
 
 The State and the Meaning of State Activity. Without going 
 into the question of what constitutes a State, it will answer our 
 purpose here to notice the extent of the conception as we use it. 
 We in the United States are familiar with many kinds of govern- 
 ment. When we speak of " the government," we generally mean 
 the federal government, with its seat at Washington. Then comes 
 the state government, then the city, the county, the township, 
 and the school district. Each of these has its own governing to 
 do, and is backed up in the doing of it by all the governments 
 superior to it. Now, it is entirely an accident with us that out of 
 these half dozen forms of government only one, and that not the 
 highest, is known as the state. In most countries the govern- 
 mental divisions most nearly corresponding to our states are known 
 by some other name departments, provinces, etc. When we 
 use the term in the present work we never mean a state in our 
 American sense unless that meaning is specified, but any society 
 acting through government. Local governments are, of course, 
 only branches of the main government. So, when a school district 
 hires a school-teacher, or a township mends a road, or a city builds 
 waterworks, or a " state " builds a penitentiary, or the federal 
 government builds a post office, all these are State activities in the 
 scientific sense of the word. So, too, when we speak of State 
 intervention we may be talking about the township or the city 
 or the general government. These are only different ways of 
 
 458
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 459 
 
 exercising one and the same kind of power that of organized 
 government. 
 
 State and Government. We use the word " State " then, in 
 its generic sense. The term " governmental activity " is some- 
 times employed but it is less desirable. The word "government" 
 suggests to the ordinary mind a power apart from and superior 
 to the people a restraining, repressing, punishing power; 
 whereas the modern concept of the State is that of a cooperative 
 institution. To those not still bound by eighteenth century tra- 
 ditions, the modern State signifies people working together. The 
 laissez-faire theory of the State is compatible with the idea of State 
 merely as government. Those under the influence of this theory 
 oppose the economic activity of the State on account of the educa- 
 tional value of private activity, not stopping to reflect that in 
 democracy the things that are done are done by the people and 
 not by an external power. It is not to be assumed without exami- 
 nation that the management of a public waterworks has an educa- 
 tional value to the people at large inferior to the educational value 
 of the management of a private waterworks. Critical examination 
 and observation will show that the advantage is not wholly with 
 either side, but that each form of enterprise has its own educa- 
 tional value. Public enterprise educates in economic affairs more 
 extensively; private enterprise more intensively. 
 
 Purity and Efficiency of the State in Relation to its Economic 
 Activities. The distinction that we have made between repres- 
 sive government and the cooperative State is especially important 
 to us, as it is in the economic sphere that the State becomes most 
 prominent as a cooperative concern. When our forefathers in 
 the eighteenth century looked upon the State as a repressive agency 
 and at the same time had an exaggerated belief in human per- 
 fectibility, they thought of the State as gradually dwindling away. 
 They entertained what is called the night-watchman theory of the 
 State. It is now clear, however, that if the repressive powers of 
 the State dwindle, its cooperative features must increase precisely 
 in the same proportion. As men improve in character their 
 fitness to act together, increases. The French philosopher, Montes- 
 quieu, more than one hundred and fifty years ago, laid down as
 
 460 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 a general principle that liberty invariably increases taxes. For 
 a similar reason the purity and efficiency of the State always 
 increase its economic activities. 
 
 We are not considering here primarily the political functions 
 of the State. The importance of preserving law and order in the 
 old restricted meaning of those terms is taken for granted. All 
 the activities of the State naturally have their economic side; and, 
 when there is a marked disturbance of law and order we appreciate 
 the fact that its maintenance is, after all, fundamental in economic 
 life, as it is in other departments of social life. All this, however, 
 is treated in political science, and need not detain us here. 
 
 General Statement of the Necessity of State Activity. The 
 experience of the last century throughout the entire civilized world 
 has convinced men that oppression and restriction are found, 
 not only within the framework of government and because of 
 government, but outside of government and in spite of govern- 
 ment. World-wide experience has shown that to secure freedom 
 it is necessary to regulate those economic relations upon which 
 our very life depends. Production has become a social process 
 and so has distribution; and social processes can be controlled 
 only socially. But " social " in this sense does not necessarily 
 mean state or governmental agencies. A great corporation is a 
 social agency, so is a trade union, a consumers' league, or a charity 
 organization society. But the supreme control is State control, 
 and this alone is all-pervasive and in its very nature' acts in the 
 interest of all. It is a perversion of a private corporation when 
 it does not act in the interest of the few who form it; it is per- 
 version of the State when it acts in the interest of the few and not 
 of the many. Thus we see in broad, general outlines the neces- 
 sity for State activity in the economic life. 
 
 The State and the Fundamental Economic Institutions of 
 Society. We may trace out the necessity for State activity very 
 briefly along a few lines. First, we will take up the institutional 
 field. The State establishes great fundamental institutions of 
 society, such as property and contract, already discussed in Chapter 
 II. Without the State we may have possession; it is only through 
 the State that possession becomes property. Without the State
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 461 
 
 we may have agreement enforceable by the strong right arm of an 
 interested party. The State steps in and makes agreements 
 enforceable by its authority and they become contracts. The 
 fundamental institutions of society are a matter of growth and are 
 in a state of flux. They change more or less from time to time and 
 from place to place. The inheritance of property has as many 
 different regulations as there are States in the world. Every 
 modification of any one of the fundamental institutions modifies 
 economic life in general and the distribution of wealth in particular. 
 As society becomes closely knitted and compact, the necessity 
 of understanding the significance of the regulation of the funda- 
 mental institutions becomes increasingly apparent. If society 
 is to be prosperous in all its members, we must have before us 
 clearly a goal which we wish to reach and so shape our institu- 
 tions as to enable us to reach the desired end. This does not mean 
 any acceptance or arbitrary construction of Utopias, inasmuch 
 as human nature has to be taken account of and the fact that it 
 has been molded by past institutions and the past modes of pro- 
 duction and exchange. It does mean, however, that we must use 
 the same intelligence in constructing our economic policies that 
 we do in constructing our private business policies. 
 
 Property, Private and Public. The right of private property 
 is one so fundamental in our modern life that we scarcely think 
 of it as a creation of man maintained by constant vigilance 
 on the part of the State and subject to human modification. Still 
 less, perhaps, does it seem to us a right open to question. It 
 seems like bed rock, an ultimate right, needing no other justifi- 
 cation than its own obviousness. It we feel thus, however, about 
 the right of private property or ownership it is only because we are 
 dominated by present and local customs rather than by the facts 
 of history or reason. We do not intend to impeach the right of 
 private ownership, but it is a right which may as fairly be called 
 in question as any other and must justify itself in the same manner. 
 When a custom has obtained very widely and is deeply rooted in 
 human life there is often a tendency to claim it as a " natural 
 right." By a natural right men usually mean a right which is 
 arbitrary, which is a right because it is a right, and " That's all
 
 462 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 there is about it." There are no such rights. All true rights are 
 rational rights, rights which can show good reason for their claims 
 and can justify their existence on the ground that they promote 
 human welfare. 
 
 There is no possible basis of human right except human 
 welfare. To claim that certain rights are ultimate without refer- 
 ence to their effect on society is to beg the question, and has been 
 well characterized as " dogmatism in disguise." It is characteristic 
 of unscientific and superficial thought to talk much of natural 
 rights, and it is an encouraging sign that in our day such rights are 
 subjected more and more to searching scrutiny. It is, therefore, 
 as scientists rather than as iconoclasts that we should inquire into 
 this time-honored right of private property. 
 
 1. Beginning of the Right. Looking back into history we 
 discover first that private property did not always exist. The 
 savage at first owned nothing. Doubtless when he had caught 
 or killed an animal he considered it more or less his, though even 
 here it was the common property of the family or tribe rather than 
 his own. Beyond this there were no property rights as we now 
 understand them. Doubtless there were struggles for the pos- 
 session of hunting grounds, but the victor's sense of ownership or 
 right was little better developed than that of a victorious lion or 
 buffalo. From these insignificant beginnings the right or sense 
 of ownership has grown, including more and more articles and 
 dividing up the ownership more and more, until at last nearly 
 everything is owned and nearly everybody owns something. Not 
 until the agricultural stage did land become property, and the last 
 forms of tribal ownership have not yet everywhere disappeared 
 before individual ownership. 
 
 2. Strengthening of the Right. The next thing that impresses 
 us is that private ownership has not always been so extensive or 
 so exclusive as at present. We have seen already that the insti- 
 tution of private property has been extended to many things which 
 were at first free goods. It is equally noticeable that the right of 
 ownership has grown in intensity and exclusiveness. This is 
 especially marked in the case of individuals whose claims as op- 
 posed to those of the tribe were at first slight and vague; but they
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 463 
 
 gradually grew, especially in the case of the chieftain, until tribal 
 or communal rights broke down before them. The time was 
 when a Scottish clan had absolute right to the territory they 
 occupied, and no chieftain, however powerful, could have abridged 
 that right. Now there are beautiful tracts of country in Scotland 
 which are almost denuded of their agricultural population because 
 the owners, the descendants of these same chieftains, have pre- 
 ferred to raise game rather than men on their estates. All are 
 familiar with the general liberty allowed in this country of hunting 
 and fishing on private estates, which in Europe is unheard of. 
 Slowly, however, we are beginning to extend our claim to game 
 and fish also, and this leniency of ownership is disappearing. 
 
 The nature and extent of these changes in private property must 
 be controlled by the State in the public interest. How far inter- 
 ference with the right is justified cannot be discussed in general 
 terms: such a discussion must deal with the specific problems of 
 municipal ownership, railway regulation, and innumerable others. 
 The point to be emphasized here is that in solving such problems 
 the mere fact that a proposed solution restricts or enlarges the 
 right of private property cannot itself be given much weight. 
 
 Trade-Marks, Copyrights, and Patents. Closely connected 
 with the general subject of property is a legal arrangement 
 whereby exclusive privileges are awarded in return for ser- 
 vices to society. These privileges become a special form of pri- 
 vate property, and have particular significance in the distribution 
 of wealth, although they are not without importance in the pro- 
 duction of wealth on account of the stimulus which they give to 
 improvement. 
 
 Trade-marks come under this head. They give property in a 
 design which characterizes the product of a single undertaking, 
 as an individual manufacturer, a firm, or a company. It is alto- 
 gether desirable that those who, by the superiority of their wares, 
 establish a reputation should be protected from that contemptible 
 class who, without energy or initiative of their own, attempt to 
 steal the fruits of the exertions of others. It encourages a pro- 
 ducer to establish a reputation to know that he can distinguish his 
 goods by a design which others may not imitate.
 
 464 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Copyrights and Patents. Government creates exclusive privi- 
 leges by copyright and patent laws; but this is done professedly 
 in the interest of the general public, and not of any favored class. 
 Authors and inventors are granted exclusive rights in their pro- 
 ductions for a limited period. This monopoly is considered a fit 
 reward for valuable public services. Copyrights and patents have 
 been objected to as interferences with natural liberty, but they 
 appear to have justified themselves in the stimulus which they have 
 given to authorship and invention. It must, however, be remem- 
 bered that all intellectual effort is an historical product. The 
 telephone, for example, did not spring from the mind of one man, 
 as Minerva from the head of Jupiter. The telephone was preceded 
 by a century of scientific invention and discovery, most of it poorly 
 enough remunerated. The telegraph was, similarly, the result 
 of generations of careful, plodding industry of scores of men. 
 Professor Henry, of Princeton College, whose services in connection 
 with the completion of the telegraph were most distinguished, con- 
 scientiously refused to take out any patent. It also happens that 
 several persons almost simultaneously and independently made 
 the same discoveries and inventions. Now, if the man who makes 
 the finishing touches which lead to utilization of a long line of 
 work alone is rewarded, it is like paying only the workman who 
 put the roof on the house. It is not generally understood how 
 serious an interference with liberty patents are. A man who has 
 a patent is allowed to say to all the rest of the world, " Because I 
 have first done such and such things you must not do them." 
 Yet there may be those who, about the same time, without any 
 knowledge of him, had found out how to do them. When a prin- 
 ciple existing in nature is allowed to be patented, and not merely 
 the application of the principle, the interference with liberty be- 
 comes still stronger. The practical conclusion is somewhat like 
 this: Patents, like copyrights, are beneficial. Experience seems 
 to warrant this assertion. Patents do not, however, rest on so 
 strong a basis as copyrights, because no two persons could ever 
 write precisely the same book, and the fact that I have written 
 a book in no wise keeps you from writing any book you please. 
 Yet even intellectual effort is largely a social product. No great
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 465 
 
 author gives the world what was merely evolved out of himself. 
 On the contrary, such a one lets an age speak through him. The 
 principle which should govern copyrights is a clear one. It is to 
 give an author reward for his services, not to give persons a reward 
 for services which others have performed. As has been well said, 
 were not copyrights limited we might now have a " Duke of Shake- 
 speare," deriving a large income from the services of a man who 
 lived three hundred years ago. 
 
 Patents should not be granted on light and trivial grounds, and 
 the period for which they are granted ought to be strictly limited, 
 and subterfuges for the evasion of this limitation ought not to be 
 suffered to succeed as at present. Moreover, owners of patents 
 ought .to receive their patents on conditions which will compel 
 them to use them or allow them to lapse; also, to grant to others 
 the right to use the patent on payment of a reasonable royalty. 
 It has also been found beneficial in some countries to lay an annual 
 and perhaps slightly progressive tax on patents, so that those 
 which are not important or not used may not interfere with indus- 
 trial progress, for it is a condition that non-payment of the tax 
 works forfeiture of the patent. Laws ought also to be changed so 
 as to prevent such an abuse of patents as we have frequently wit- 
 nessed in our rural districts, where farmers have been induced to 
 infringe patents unwittingly in order that damages might be 
 collected from them. The suggestion of a former commissioner 
 of patents, that the right of purchase of a patent be reserved by 
 the United States, is to be commended. Our patents at the 
 present time promote monopoly, and in some cases interfere 
 seriously, it is to be feared, with manufactures. The patent 
 laws require to be simplified and amended and their abuses re- 
 moved. At the same time reward should in some way always be 
 provided for those who make valuable inventions. 
 
 Public Property. Public property operates to diffuse wealth; 
 this is in its very nature. We may contrast, for example, the post 
 office in the United States, which has given rise to no large fortunes, 
 with the railways in the United States, which have been the source 
 of many mammoth fortunes. On the other hand, when the post 
 office has been a private institution, as it was for centuries on the 
 
 2 H
 
 466 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Continent of Europe, it was a source of enormous fortunes. There 
 are very many aspects of public and private ownership, but their 
 respective influence upon the distribution of wealth is of growing 
 importance and is destined to occupy the increasing attention of 
 economists and publicists. The relations of public to private 
 property will be shaped with reference to the prevailing ideas of 
 wealth distribution. 
 
 Inheritance of Property. As Blackstone stated so clearly 
 in his Commentaries on the Laws of England, and as we have 
 already seen in Chapter II, the inheritance of property is a different 
 fundamental institution from the right of property. The laws 
 governing the inheritance of property determine to whom the right 
 of property shall pass. 1 These laws of inheritance, as already 
 stated, are constantly undergoing change, and have as many dif- 
 ferent forms as there are authorities regulating inheritance of 
 property. That which seems a mere natural right at one time 
 seems a natural wrong at another, as illustrated in the changing 
 ideas and practice concerning the share of a father's estate to be 
 inherited by the oldest son. The laws of inheritance are of prime 
 force in the distribution of wealth, and every change in them modi- 
 fies the distribution of wealth. In a society becoming increasingly 
 self-conscious, it is necessary to regulate inheritance in accordance 
 with those ideas concerning the diffusion of property which are 
 accepted as the best. 
 
 Contract. Unregulated contract cannot be free in any real 
 sense of the term because back of contract lie all the inequalities 
 and injustices found in human society. Contract can be free and 
 equal only when the men making it are free and equal. We have 
 in consequence the necessity of regulating contract in the general 
 interest; and this is recognized in every country in the civilized 
 world. It is especially marked in labor legislation, where the lais- 
 sez-faire theory has utterly broken down. Where the processes 
 of production are social, an individual cannot regulate individually 
 those relations which are determined by contract. The hours of 
 
 1 We use the term "inheritance" in its broadest sense, not distinguishing it from 
 "bequest." It includes all those arrangements which determine how property 
 shall pass from one generation to another.
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 467 
 
 labor, for example, are socially determined. An employee in a 
 great manufacturing establishment has his hours determined first 
 of all by his immediate employer. If he does not accept these 
 hours, he must quit work. The employer may be a great corpora- 
 don, but even in that case the employer himself has only a limited 
 power in determining the length of the working day, inasmuch as 
 he has to produce goods and services in competition with others, 
 and he likewise must have regard for general conditions. These 
 general conditions must be determined legislatively and admin- 
 istratively. Even a modern nation like France does not find itself 
 wholly free, and has thought it necessary to make an international 
 treaty with Italy to determine conditions of toil both in Italy and 
 in France. This treaty, dated April 15, 1905, marks a great epoch 
 in the history of labor legislation. It was the first of its kind in 
 the world's history, but has been followed by others. It shows 
 the anachronism of those who say that men, women, and children 
 must be allowed to work as many hours as they please. They can 
 do what they please only as they work socially and bring their 
 social will to bear upon individual conditions. This was conceded 
 first of all with respect to children. Later, after much resistance, 
 it found recognition in the case of women. Men, on account of 
 their greater physical strength and their superior economic effi- 
 ciency, especially in organization, are better able to regulate their 
 conditions of toil individually and through organizations, but all 
 the best authorities now recognize that there are many cases in 
 which it is necessary to regulate the labor contract of adult men. 
 
 Ethical Level of Competition. One of the main lines of activ- 
 ity of the State in economic life consists in regulating the ethical 
 level of competition. One of the great morements of our times 
 consists in the effort to remove the evils of competition, not by its 
 abolition, but by its ethical regulation. When it is forbidden 
 manufacturers to employ children, competition exists, but the ethi- 
 cal level is raised. An almost endless number of illustrations is 
 afforded by the legislation in our own and other countries during 
 the past generation. Pure food laws afford the most marked recent 
 illustration. 
 
 The Consumer. John Stuart Mill recognized that there were
 
 468 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 many cases in which the consumer could not determine the qual- 
 ity of the commodities offered him by the producer, and this 
 was treated by him as one of the exceptions to the general rule 
 of governmental non-interference. He instanced education as a 
 case in which the greater the need of the consumer the less his 
 capacity to pass judgment upon the kind of education offered. 
 We have seen during the past fifty years a continually widening 
 field of State activity to protect the consumer in these cases in 
 which he cannot protect himself. This growing activity of the 
 State is recognized by modern civilization as a necessity. It now 
 embraces the inspection of food products, and it has been demon- 
 strated conclusively that very generally the consumer is unable 
 to pass judgment upon the quality of the food which he purchases. 
 He is unable to detect the presence of even most injurious poisons. 
 It is seen that the public health is involved in this sort of economic 
 activity. After long resistance to food inspection and certification 
 in the United States, the first concession was made on account of 
 foreign pressure. Germany, in particular, was unwilling to receive 
 our meats until they had been inspected. A growing movement 
 in favor of protecting the consumer has found its culmination in 
 the Pure Food Act passed by Congress in 1906. 
 
 As John Stuart Mill so well said long ago, we can draw no arbi- 
 trary line or ring fence around the activity of government. In 
 every case it has to be determined by considerations of public 
 utility. 
 
 Monopolies, Government Ownership, etc. Wherever competi- 
 tion is absent, there is necessity for State activity which must take 
 the form of public ownership and operation or of control of cor- 
 porations. This subject, however, has been discussed in another 
 chapter. 
 
 The State the Guardian of the Permanent Economic In- 
 terests of Society. The State is conceived of as having im- 
 mortality. No definite limit can be placed to its life, and all its 
 plans must be made with reference to perpetuity of existence. 
 Were any public policies to be framed on the hypothesis of the 
 decay and death of the State, it would indicate in itself an almost 
 inconceivably deplorable condition of society. It is therefore
 
 NECESSITY OF STATE ACTIVITY 469 
 
 necessary that the State, as the representative of all the members 
 of the body politic and of all generations, should particularly care 
 for permanent interests. It alone has the nature and the power 
 equal to this task. 
 
 This proposition finds most clear illustration in forestry. With- 
 out going into other technical details, the mere fact that rational 
 forestry requires plans to be made for perhaps one hundred years 
 in advance makes it difficult for private persons to safeguard our 
 interests in this particular. The experience of the civilized world, 
 that of the United States included, shows conclusively that only 
 large State activity, including a great deal of public ownership 
 and management, can provide adequately for our varied forestry 
 needs. Federal government as well as our separate common- 
 wealths have made a good beginning, but it is only a beginning; 
 and in floods and drought we suffer average annual losses of 
 many millions which would have been obviated had we begun 
 our activity earlier and carried it on more extensively. 
 
 The same principles apply in large measure to our great natural 
 resources, such as coal and iron, and our vast water power. The 
 conservation of our natural resources for the general good " for 
 and by the people " is one of the greatest economic problems 
 of the day. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Why do we speak of the economic functions of the State rather than of 
 government ? Is this distinction merely convenient, or is it absolute ? Do 
 you feel that you are governed by the post office ? How do you help make it 
 a cooperative institution? 
 
 2. Mention any illustrations of the propositions that purity and efficiency 
 of the State increase its functions. 
 
 3. Would your personal freedom be increased if the economic activities 
 of the state, city, or town in which you live were decreased ? 
 
 4. Why is it necessary that the State should be active with respect to prop- 
 erty and contract? Does unregulated labor contract mean servitude and 
 oppression ? If so, why ? If not, why not ? What is the significance of the 
 fact that modern approximations to slavery rest upon contract nominally 
 free? Discuss this proposition: "There is no greater inequality than the 
 equal treatment of unequals." If a woman works fourteen hours a day in 
 a sweat shop, is her contract to do so an expression of her freedom ?
 
 470 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 5. Do copyrights interfere less with industrial liberty than patents? If 
 so, why ? Would it be unjust to refuse to grant patents hereafter ? Would 
 it be inexpedient ? Why ? 
 
 6. Contrast public property with private property in its effects (a) on the 
 production, (b) on the diffusion, of wealth. 
 
 7. Explain the reasons for the increase in public activity in the inspection 
 of food products. What evils and what benefits of this public activity have 
 fallen under your observation? 
 
 8. What other kinds of State activity are discussed in this chapter ? Give 
 the reasons for each. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ADAMS, H. C. " Relation of the State to Industrial Action." American 
 
 Economic Association Publication, 1887. 
 Agricultural Department. Year Book. 
 Annual Reports of the United States Commissioner of Patents, especially the 
 
 Report for 1888. 
 Reports of the Wisconsin Dairy and Food Commission.
 
 CHAPTER XXVII 
 TRANSPORTATION 
 
 Scope and Significance. A complete study of transportation 
 would include a variety of subjects, as is seen from the following 
 outline: 
 
 I. Transmission of Ideas. 
 
 (1) The Post Office. 
 
 (2) The Telegraph. 
 
 (3) The Telephone. 
 II. Land Transportation. 
 
 (1) Steam Railways. 
 
 (2) Interurban and City Railways. 
 
 (3) Vehicles on the Common Roads. 
 III. Water Transportation. 
 
 (1) Ocean. 
 
 (2) Inland. 
 
 a. Canals. 
 
 b. Rivers. 
 
 c. Lakes. 
 
 Transportation may be studied from a number of points of view, 
 all of them closely related. It presents its peculiar problems to 
 the engineer, to the lawyer, to the accountant, to the business 
 manager, to the historian, and finally to the economist. The 
 economist studies the relations of transportation to other indus- 
 tries and to the public welfare. The heart of the subject from 
 this point of view is the question of rates and fares. 
 
 Transportation is most intimately related to the other branches 
 of industry. Hardly anything can be produced without the
 
 472 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 participation of some transportation agent. Modern industrial 
 civilization would be impossible without an efficient system of com- 
 mercial intercourse, although to be sure the dependence is not one- 
 sided, but is mutual, for present methods of transportation clearly 
 would be impossible without our industrial progress. The in- 
 fluence of cheap carriage is especially important in the fact that 
 it promotes an extensive division of labor by widening the market. 
 It permits each region to devote itself to that line of production 
 for which it is best adapted. 
 
 In the present chapter, railway transportation alone will be 
 considered, although the subject of water transportation is as- 
 suming increasing importance in the United States. We are 
 beginning to realize that the reaction against the early canal 
 mania has been too great. Canal and river improvement, how- 
 ever, should be urged, not on the general ground that water 
 transportation is cheap, but only where in specific instances it 
 can be proved to be as advantageous as rail transportation when 
 all of the elements of expense are taken into consideration. 
 Nor should canal building be advocated as a means of controlling 
 railway rates. If we wish to regulate the charges of private 
 carriers, a commission of trained men is the best device we have 
 yet discovered. 
 
 The Railway System of the United States. The aggregate 
 length of railway mileage on June 30, 1906, was 224,363 miles. 
 The most important states with respect to length of line were 
 Texas, Illinois, Pennsylvania, Iowa, and Ohio. In number of 
 miles of line per 10,000 inhabitants, the leading states or territories 
 were: Nevada, Arizona, Wyoming, New Mexico, and Montana, 
 but in number of miles of line per 100 square miles of territory, 
 the lead was taken by the District of Columbia, New Jersey, 
 Massachusetts, Pennsylvania, and Ohio. The foregoing refers to 
 the length of road without regard to the second, third, or fourth 
 tracks. To operate this mileage the railway companies employ 
 about 3^ per cent of the persons engaged in gainful occupations 
 in the United States. The numerical strength and average 
 daily wages of each class of employees is given in the following 
 table :
 
 TRANSPORTATION 
 
 473 
 
 TABLE I 
 CLASSIFICATION or EMPLOYEES 1906 
 
 CLASS 
 
 NUMBER 
 
 AVERAGE DAILY 
 COMPENSATION 
 
 General officers 6,090 
 
 Other officers 6,705 
 
 General office clerks 57i2io 
 
 Station agents 34,940 
 
 Other station men 138,778 
 
 Enginemen 59,855 
 
 Firemen 62,678 
 
 Conductors 43,93^ 
 
 Other trainmen 119,087 
 
 Machinists 5 X 2 53 
 
 Carpenters 63,830 
 
 Other shopmen 199,940 
 
 Section foremen 40,463 
 
 Other trackmen 343,791 
 
 Switch tenders, crossing tenders, and watch- 
 men 49,659 
 
 Telegraph operators and dispatchers 36,090 
 
 Employees account floating equipment. .. . 8,314 
 
 All other employees and laborers 198,736 
 
 Total 1,521,355 
 
 Sn.8i 
 5-82 
 2.24 
 1.94 
 1.69 
 4.12 
 2.42 
 3-5i 
 2-35 
 2.69 
 2.28 
 1.92 
 i. 80 
 1.36 
 
 1.80 
 
 2-!3 
 2.IO 
 
 1.83 
 
 The amount of passenger service in a year is sufficient to give 
 every man, woman, and child in the United States a journey of 
 over two hundred miles, and the amount of freight reported as 
 carried (originating on line) is more than ten tons for each inhab- 
 itant (1900). The mileage of empty freight cars is nearly half 
 as large as the mileage of loaded freight cars. 
 
 In 1906 there were 1287 operating roads in the United States, 
 of which 1007 were nominally independent. Nine tenths of these 
 lines are less than 250 miles in length, and represent less than a 
 fifth of the total mileage. On the other hand, the fifty largest 
 roads control about two thirds of the total mileage. 
 
 Railway Competition. The early roads were short, independ-
 
 474 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ent lines largely for local traffic or to serve as feeders to canals. 
 The first movement toward the efficiency of the present system 
 was the welding together of separate links into through lines. 
 The New York Central, for example, was formed in 1853 out of 
 ten previously independent lines between Albany and Buffalo. 
 The development of parallel through lines introduced an era of 
 sharp competition. In the seventies the lines connecting Chicago 
 and the Atlantic seaboard engaged in a series of rate wars. The 
 experience of this decade showed clearly the tempo rary and un- 
 stable character of competition among parallel lines. The rule 
 seemed to be that a railway war must be followed by a rate agree- 
 ment of some sort, so that, instead of the maintenance of a suppos- 
 edly fair level of rates by the steady pressure of competition, we 
 find there was an alternation of high and low rates. The inevi- 
 table annihilation of direct competition in rates between railways 
 is clearly portrayed in a congressional report in 1874, where the 
 following prediction was made: " But when the natural tendencies 
 of corporate power have wrought out their inevitable conclusions, 
 the magnitude of our combinations will probably be in proportion 
 to the extent of the field in which they operate." But so strong 
 was the feeling at that time that competition is the life of trade, 
 that it was recommended by the committee who made this report 
 that the government build a line of its own simply to maintain 
 competition with the private roads, for it was thought that the 
 government could resist the great temptation to combine with the 
 other roads. 
 
 The history of Belgium affords an instructive illustration of the effect of 
 a mixed system of public and private ownership. Belgium began in 1837 
 with a carefully worked-out system of public railways. Ten years later it 
 was decided to grant charters to private companies. A large number of 
 private roads were organized, some with the purpose of competing with the 
 state system. It was thought that competition between the state and private 
 roads would be beneficial. The Massachusetts Railroad Commission, in its 
 report of 1871, recommended a trial of this plan in Massachusetts But in 
 Belgium the private lines were soon merged into four systems, which com- 
 peted so vigorously with the state roads that the government adopted the 
 policy of purchasing them. The mixed system was also tried in Prussia with 
 unfavorable results. The advantages of government management cannot 
 show themselves fully under such conditions.
 
 TRANSPORTATION 475 
 
 Pooling and Consolidation. As a result of the intense struggle 
 for business among the roads, there was a widespread resort to 
 the practice of pooling, that is, a division of the earnings or tonnage 
 of the competitive business. This form of combination, however, 
 was at least nominally abandoned after it was declared illegal 
 by the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887, but organizations for the 
 purpose of making rates continued to exist. In 1894 these were 
 also declared illegal by the Supreme Court of the United States 
 on the ground that they were in violation of the Anti-Trust Act of 
 1890. The court, however, did not seem to prohibit the enlarge- 
 ment of the various systems by the purchase and lease of other 
 lines, or controlling them indirectly by the purchase of the ma- 
 jority of their stock. But in 1903 the Supreme Court again 
 applied the Anti-Trust Act of 1890 in a case against the Northern 
 Securities Company, a corporation formed, not for the purpose of 
 engaging in the railway business directly, but for the purpose of 
 holding the capital stock of the Great Northern, Northern Pacific, 
 and Burlington systems. But the legal prohibitions have had 
 little effect upon the tendency to eliminate competition from the 
 railway business. 
 
 The present organization of any one of our large systems, like 
 a geological record, reveals the nature of the changes that have 
 been going on. The consolidated company controls a number of 
 large lines, perhaps by stock ownership, and each one of these is 
 made up of a number of subsidiary roads united as a result of 
 purchase, partial-stock ownership, or lease. 
 
 But the extent of consolidation is not shown by the growth of 
 the large systems, for these are not wholly independent. A 
 number of the large systems may be under the control of the same 
 group of financiers. While the actual extent of this centralization 
 in ownership is difficult to state, the well-known illustrations are 
 striking: the Harriman group includes the Union Pacific, the 
 Southern Pacific, the Illinois Central, and the Chicago and Alton 
 systems, with partial control of the Baltimore and Ohio. In 
 the Gould group are: the Missouri Pacific, Wabash, Denver and 
 Rio Grande, Western Pacific, Texas and Pacific, and the St. Louis 
 and Southwestern systems. The Great Northern, Northern Pa-
 
 476 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 cific, and Burlington systems are under one control. The Penn- 
 sylvania until recently controlled the Baltimore and Ohio and 
 Norfolk and Western systems. The Vanderbilt interests domi- 
 nate the New York Central, the Chicago and Northwestern, and 
 the Cleveland, Cincinnati, Chicago, and St. Louis systems. 
 
 In spite of the progress of consolidation, competition has not 
 entirely disappeared. Even where there is no active cutting of 
 rates by parallel lines, there may be rivalry in service, but this 
 also has its limitations, as is seen in the agreements that the shorter 
 lines between New York and Chicago and between Chicago and 
 Minneapolis shall not utilize their natural advantage in speed. 
 Again, alternative routes may lead to competition among railways 
 that are not parallel. Thus the roads serving the North Atlantic 
 ports compete in the carriage of grain with those extending to 
 Galveston and New Orleans. 
 
 Much has recently been said about the influence of market 
 competition as a force affecting rates, even when the roads have 
 been consolidated. To illustrate, the farmers and railways of 
 North Dakota are joint producers of wheat, and they are both 
 desirous that it shall be sold in competition with other wheat in 
 the London market. It would be ruinous to the roads to make 
 such high rates that the farmers could not afford to sell their grain. 
 The railways cannot be prosperous if the farmers, merchants, 
 and manufacturers along their lines are not prosperous. This 
 partnership, however, has its limits, for a rate which would enable 
 the producer to continue in business may yield the railway a sur- 
 plus which could be shared with the producer. 
 
 The MoTement of Rates. The average revenue per ton-mile 
 of railways in the United States fell from i.ooi cents in 1888 to 
 .729 cents in 1900, rising again to .780 in 1904, .766 in 1905, and 
 .748 in 1906. Average ton-mile receipts, however, are not an 
 accurate index of changes in rates, for such an index is affected 
 by the changes in the nature of the traffic as well as by changes 
 in rates charged. If the proportion of low-grade freight increases, 
 there will be a fall in ton-mile receipts without any change in rates. 
 But if we also take into consideration rates on specific commodities, 
 such as wheat, stoves, etc., no doubt remains but that a large
 
 TRANSPORTATION 477 
 
 decrease has taken place. In the last forty years there has prob- 
 ably been a fall of one half in rates on through traffic, but the fall 
 was mostly in the first half of that period; in the second half there 
 has been only a slight fall, with possibly some increase since 1900. 
 In local rates the decline has been less marked. The decline in 
 passenger rates before the recent reductions by government au- 
 thority was less than in freight rates. Improvement in service 
 should, however, be considered in this connection. But what- 
 ever the actual movement of rates, the question will inevitably be 
 asked whether they have declined as much as they should have 
 done, and whether the growth in consolidation which we have 
 noted will not prevent such a decline in the future as may be 
 warranted by the growth in traffic and attendant economies in 
 operation. The question is, how shall a "reasonable" freight 
 rate be determined? 
 
 The Level of Rates. If, owing to the monopolistic nature of 
 the railway business, the determination of rates can no longer be 
 left to the automatic working of competitive forces, they must 
 be consciously determined according to fundamental principles. 
 Competition was supposed to do justice by limiting the aggregate 
 earnings of an establishment approximately to the expenses of 
 doing the business, and it seems most natural that we should apply 
 the same guide in our conscious rate making. There can be no 
 doubt but that expense is a safe guide so far as it can be accurately 
 determined. It needs but a slight analysis of railway expenditure, 
 however, to reveal the difficulty of using expense as a criterion of a 
 fair rate. In 1906 the railways reported to the Interstate Com- 
 merce Commission gross income amounting to $2,386,285,473 
 (from operation and investments), and in this same year the interest 
 and dividends amounted to $530,545,911, or 22.2 per cent of the 
 gross income. This represents the amount accruing to the stock 
 and bondholders as joint owners of the business, if we ignore the 
 increase in the value of the plant that results from charging im- 
 provements to operating expenses. Is this a proper payment to 
 such owners? That some compensation of this sort is necessary 
 under the regime of private capitalism is clear, for if none were 
 made, new roads would not be built nor would old ones be main'
 
 478 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tained. A common answer is that the owners should be allowed 
 a fair return upon their investment, but it is difficult to say what is 
 a fair return and what is the actual investment. Inasmuch as 
 the institution of private capitalism is maintained for the benefit 
 of the community and not the community for the benefit of private 
 capitalism, that payment to owners of the railways is proper which 
 is necessary to evoke their services, that is, the service of main 
 taining and extending the railway system in accordance with the 
 public needs. This basis suggests the application of the current 
 rate of interest to the cost of reproducing the physical property 
 in its present condition as a general guide, although doubtless 
 our regard for vested interests would compel us to take account 
 of the fact that present holders of stocks and bonds have in many 
 cases paid high prices for them in anticipation of the continuance 
 of the present monopoly earnings of the railways. It should 
 also be remembered that to guarantee to every dollar invested in 
 railways the current rate of interest would be to create a privi- 
 leged class of investors. 1 The attempt to find a valuation upon 
 which to reckon earnings has been sharply criticised, but no other 
 solution for the problem of finding a reasonable level of rates has 
 been offered. Reject this, and we have the alternative of letting 
 the railways charge what they please, or of adopting government 
 ownership. 
 
 Relative Rates. When the level of rates has been determined 
 we are confronted by the further question of what should be 
 charged for each particular shipment, and here we find the applica- 
 tion of the principle of expense of still greater difficulty and un- 
 certainty. In attempting to say what it costs to carry a ton of 
 coal a mile, we find that a large part of the expenditure is incurred, 
 not for one specific kind of commodity, but jointly for many kinds. 
 The roadbed, ties, and rails are maintained, not for coal cars 
 alone, but for passenger trains as well. Even with the most care- 
 ful bookkeeping it is possible to trace a causal connection between 
 only a part of the expenses and specific portions of the traffic. 
 
 1 This principle has been recognized by the Supreme Court of the United States 
 in County of Stanislaus (California) vs. San Joaquin and King's River C. & I. 
 Co., 1903, 193 U.S. 201. Compare also page an, above.
 
 TRANSPORTATION 479 
 
 It is possible to say that a certain traffic requires a certain amount 
 of extra labor and fuel, and causes a certain amount of wear and 
 tear, and clearly such traffic should normally pay enough to meet 
 these expenses, at least, if we wish to prevent waste. But what 
 shall be done with such joint expenditures as fall under the head of 
 maintenance of way? Shall they be charged to the freight or to 
 the passenger departments? If partly to both, on what basis 
 shall they be divided ? A full discussion of the matter cannot be 
 given here. Some writers think that the attempt to discover the 
 exact cost of carrying a commodity cannot be determined. They 
 would charge these common expenses to those shipments which 
 can most easily bear them. This principle is followed in part in 
 all freight classifications. But recently the view that the cost of 
 transporting a commodity can be determined has received support 
 in a decision of the Railroad Commission of Wisconsin. Follow- 
 ing the practice of manufacturing corporations, the commission 
 made a complete apportionment to the freight and passenger de- 
 partments of the expenditures of one railway system, using an arbi- 
 trary basis that seemed fair where no direct connection could be 
 found between the expense and each branch of the traffic. 
 
 To illustrate the nature of the problem, we may note the Commission's 
 method of dealing with one class of expenditure maintenance of way. 
 It was necessary first to apportion expenditures between that part of the road 
 lying in Wisconsin and that part lying in other states. For this purpose 
 the cost of maintaining the way was first divided into two parts: (a) that 
 depending on natural depreciation, and (b) that due to the movement of 
 trains. The first was apportioned to Wisconsin on the basis of the road 
 mileage, and the second according to the revenue train mileage in Wisconsin. 
 The Commission then proceeded to separate the Wisconsin expenditure 
 between the passenger and freight departments. That part of the expense 
 due to the movement of trains was divided between passenger and freight 
 traffic according to the amount of passenger train mileage and freight train 
 mileage respectively, switching mileage being taken as freight train mileage. 
 That part due to natural depreciation was apportioned according to the gross 
 earnings of the two departments. This last procedure is perhaps open to 
 criticism because gross earnings depend in part on prices charged, and it was 
 the reasonableness of existing prices that it was sought to determine. In the 
 long run the natural depreciation depends on how costly a plant is exposed 
 to wind and weather; in the long run the size of the plant grows with the 
 traffic; and as traffic is roughly measured by train mileage, we may say
 
 480 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 that train mileage would be a more reasonable basis for the division of 
 expenses due to natural depreciation. 1 
 
 Distance. The most perplexing factor in rate making is that 
 of distance. In actual practice, distance has been ignored to a 
 very large degree. For example, in group rates, the same charge 
 is made to a common market from any point within a certain area, 
 irrespective of the length of the haul. In the basing-point system, 
 the rates to small towns in a certain region will not vary according 
 to the distance from the point of shipment, but are found by adding 
 together the rate to a railway center, called a basing point, and the 
 local rate from this basing point to the small town, even though 
 the town be nearer than the basing point to the original point of 
 shipment. Again, goods brought from a foreign country to a 
 point in the interior may be charged a less rate than the domestic 
 rate from the point of entry to the same point in the interior. 
 Again, goods intended for export sent from Chicago to New York 
 may pay less than those intended for use in New York. Goods 
 are sent to San Francisco from New York for less than the rate 
 from many points west of the Mississippi River to San Francisco. 
 These conditions have arisen largely from competition of rail- 
 ways among themselves and with waterways, and do not seem 
 to be necessary from the standpoint of the welfare of the country 
 as a whole. The fact that distance is one element in the expense 
 of carriage suggests that it should be taken account of in making 
 rates, although there are many circumstances which necessitate 
 a departure from the rule of a strict mileage rate. The fact that 
 terminal charges, for example, are the same for a long as for a 
 short haul justifies a decline in the total charge per ton-mile as 
 distance grows. The great advantage of following a schedule of 
 rates based on distance is that it affords some basis, although not 
 an absolute guide, for settling sectional disputes concerning rail- 
 way charges. 
 
 Government Ownership or Government Regulation? With 
 the decline of competition in the railway business, the alternative 
 lies between private operation with government supervision on 
 
 1 In Buel vs. C. M. and St. P. Ry. Co., Wisconsin Railroad Commission 
 Reports, Vol. I, pp. 334 and 508.
 
 TRANSPORTATION 481 
 
 the one hand, and government ownership and operation on the 
 other. The important arguments in favor of private operation 
 are: (i) efficiency in management; (2) greater elasticity in meeting 
 the varying demands of business; (3) the danger in government 
 operation of throwing sectional disputes as to rates into politics. 
 The important arguments in favor of government operation are: 
 (i) the essential conflict between private and public interests 
 in the conduct of the business, the aim of the one being profit, the 
 aim of the other being service; (2) the elimination of the rail- 
 way interests from politics; (3) the unearned increment would 
 accrue to society; (4) the elimination of personal discrimination. 
 
 On whichever side the weight of the argument may lie, we in 
 the United States are likely to make a more thorough experi- 
 ment with private operation under government regulation. 
 
 Government Regulation of Railways in the United States. 
 Railway corporations in the United States are almost all organized 
 under the laws of the separate states. Formerly special laws were 
 passed when a railway company was to be formed, but at the pres- 
 ent time there are general laws specifying what conditions must 
 be complied with in order that a number of persons may organize 
 a railway corporation. The separate states have imposed a number 
 of regulations and restrictions not only on the companies which 
 they have chartered but also on others doing business within their 
 borders. These relate to the safety and comfort of passengers, 
 the train service, consolidations, pooling, ticket-scalping, discrimi- 
 nations between shippers and places, and finally the reasonable- 
 ness of charges. Railway commissions are found in a majority 
 of the states. One type, exemplified by the Massachusetts com- 
 mission, has simply advisory and investigative powers with respect 
 to rates, but it cannot name reasonable rates and enforce them, 
 although it can recommend such action to the legislature. An- 
 other type has power to name a reasonable rate in place of one that 
 has been found unreasonable. Such is the Wisconsin commission, 
 and the tendency is for the latter type to prevail. 
 
 That a railway corporation is subject to government regulation 
 in the interest of the public welfare has been clearly established 
 by a long line of judicial decisions beginning with the leading
 
 482 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 " Granger " case of Munn vs. Illinois. 1 But the authority of 
 the state governments has been greatly limited by two provisions 
 in the federal Constitution. Congress having been given control 
 over interstate commerce, the states must confine themselves in 
 their regulations to commerce wholly within the state. Again, 
 the Fourteenth Amendment declares that no state shall deprive 
 any person of life, liberty, or property without due process of law 
 nor deny to any person within its jurisdiction the equal protection 
 of the law. The courts have interpreted this provision to mean 
 that neither a state legislature nor a commission created by it can 
 fix rates even on iw/ra-state traffic without a review by the courts. 
 The courts have in some cases declared rate legislation void on 
 the ground that it confiscated the property of the stockholders. 
 The activity of the federal government may be summarized as 
 follows : 
 
 (i) As to rates: All charges made for the transportation of 
 passengers or property must be " just and reasonable," but no 
 standard of reasonableness or justice has been given by Congress. 
 This question is left largely to the judgment of the Interstate 
 Commerce Commission, a body of seven men appointed by the 
 President with the " advice and consent " of the Senate. When 
 a complaint has been made, the commission, if it finds upon 
 investigation that the rate complained of is unreasonable, may 
 prescribe what shall be the maximum charge in that case in the 
 future. Its order may be set aside by the courts, for the Fifth 
 Amendment restrains the federal government as the Fourteenth 
 does the state governments. Rates must be published and filed 
 with the Commission, and the railway must not under penalty 
 depart from the published rate, nor make any change without thirty 
 days' notice. There shall be no "unjust discrimination" or 
 " unreasonable preference " in the making of rates. In particular, 
 the giving or accepting of rebates is punishable. Also, no greater 
 charge shall be made for a short than for a long haul on goods 
 going in the same direction on the same line under " substantially 
 similar circumstances and conditions." This last provision has 
 been much weakened by the interpretation placed upon it by the 
 
 1 1876, 94 U.S. 113.
 
 TRANSPORTATION 483 
 
 United States Supreme Court, which has held that competition 
 of railways at one point might constitute a dissimilar circumstance 
 justifying a lower charge for the longer haul. 
 
 (2) As to publicity of accounts: The carriers are required to 
 report to the Interstate Commerce Commission regarding their 
 finances and traffic. The Commission has access to the records 
 and may prescribe the form in which they shall be kept. 
 
 (3) As to combinations: It is unlawful for railways to enter 
 into an agreement for the pooling of freights or earnings. Agree- 
 ments to maintain freight rates are also unlawful as coming under 
 the Anti-Trust Act of 1890 which prohibits " every contract, com- 
 bination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint 
 of trade or commerce among the several states, or with foreign 
 nations." 
 
 (4) As to safety appliances: Carriers must equip their cars 
 with automatic couplers, train brakes, grab irons and hand holds. 
 The law does not require the introduction of block signal systems. 
 
 The Work of the Interstate Commerce Commission. Since its 
 creation in 1887 the Interstate Commerce Commission has done 
 much good work in promoting an understanding of the relations 
 between the public and the railways, but in the actual removal 
 of abuses its powers proved utterly inadequate. As a result of a 
 wave of popular indignation, Congress in 1906 extended the Com- 
 mission's power of investigation and increased somewhat its power 
 over rates. Nothing, however, was done to give definiteness to 
 the long and short haul provision, nor were steps taken to settle 
 the fundamental question of the level of rates. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 i. Write a description of some railway system, giving its organization, 
 capitalization, earnings, dividends, nature of traffic and territory covered, etc. 
 
 2. Make a digest of the opinions in the Northern Securities case, 193 
 U.S. 197. 
 
 3. If you have paid $200 for a share of stock in a monopolistic enterprise, 
 have you a right to complain if government regulation so affects its earnings, 
 that the price of the share falls to $100? 
 
 4. Should the large shipper get lower rates than the small shipper? 
 
 5. Compare the powers of the Interstate Commerce Commission with 
 those of the Canadian Commission.
 
 484 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ACWORTH, W. M. Elements of Railway Economics, Chaps. I and II. (Not 
 favorable to cost theory.) 
 
 " American Waterways." (Twenty articles on various phases of the subject.) 
 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Jan- 
 uary, 1908, Vol. XXXI. 
 
 DEWSNUP, E. R. (Editor). Railway Organization and Working. (De- 
 scriptive.) 
 
 Hearings before the Committee on Interstate Commerce, United States 
 Senate, 1905-6 (including Digest). Digest, pp. 57-75; and Vol. Ill, 
 pp. 2310 to 2360. 
 
 Interstate Commerce Commission, Annual Reports, Decisions, and Statistics 
 of Railways in the United States. 
 
 JOHNSON, E. R. American Railway Transportation, and Ocean and Inland 
 Water Transportation. (Elementary Text-books.) 
 
 McPnERSON, L. G. The Working of the Railroads, Chap. III. 
 
 MERRITT, A. N. Federal Regulation of Railway Rates. 
 
 MEYER, B. H. Railway Legislation in the United States, Part II ; also 
 "History of the Northern Securities Case," Bulletins of the University 
 of Wisconsin, No. 142. 
 
 MEYER, H. R. Government Regulation of Railway Rates. (Severely critical 
 of the work of government officials.) 
 
 Munn vs. Illinois, 94 U.S. 113. 
 
 NOYES, W. C. American Railroad Rates, Chap. IV. 
 
 RIPLEY, W. Z. Railway Problems. (A collection of supplementary reading.) 
 " Railroad Valuation," Political Science Quarterly, December, 1907, 
 Vol. XXII. 
 
 United States vs. Trans-Missouri Freight Association, 166 U.S. 290. 
 
 WEBB. Economics of Railroad Construction, Part I.
 
 CHAPTER XXVIII 
 INSURANCE 
 
 Nature of Insurance. The essential idea of the modern in- 
 stitution of insurance is cooperation in the bearing of losses which 
 are likely to happen to any one of a large group of persons but 
 which will actually fall upon but few members of the group. It 
 is thus directly opposed to gambling, although wagers have fre- 
 quently been made in the form of the insurance contract. It 
 may appear at first that the man who insures his house is making 
 a wager with the insurance company that his house will burn, 
 but this is in fact like betting on both sides of an event. If the 
 man does not insure, he may be regarded as betting that his house 
 will not burn, and by wagering with the insurance company that 
 it will burn, he relieves himself of risk. For this relief he is willing 
 to incur the certain loss of his premium. Insurance means cer- 
 tain loss for the policy holders, but it implies many small losses 
 in place of a few unbearable ones. In well-developed forms of 
 insurance there is also no risk for the insurance company because 
 the amount of loss is approximately known in advance, as will be 
 explained presently. 
 
 The question is sometimes asked whether insurance is pro- 
 ductive in the sense that other economic activities are productive. 
 The answer is decidedly in the affirmative, for the feeling of security 
 that it makes possible is a real satisfaction which we are willing 
 to purchase. Furthermore, the relief of distress among the un- 
 fortunate without compelling them to accept charity is a distinct 
 social gain, and finally, many of our business operations are 
 facilitated by the existence of a system of insurance. Prevention 
 of loss is not properly a part of the idea of insurance, but never- 
 theless, insurance as it exists to-day does have many tendencies 
 in that direction, especially in such forms as fire and steam-boiler 
 
 485
 
 486 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 insurance. On the other hand, insurance causes a certain amount 
 of loss by provoking to some extent incendiarism, self-mutilation, 
 or suicide, and even normal persons are likely to be less careful 
 when they know they are insured. On the whole, however, we 
 can scarcely overestimate the importance to society of an in- 
 stitution which equalizes the shocks and multiplies the incentives 
 to thrift and wholesome economic activity. 
 
 The Law of Probabilities. A special profession (that of the 
 actuary) and a special branch of mathematics have grown up as 
 a basis of the institution of insurance. It is a knowledge of the 
 law of large numbers that changes the insurance business from a 
 wager to a legitimate business. If a coin is tossed a large number 
 of times, heads will appear about as often as tails. This may be 
 counted upon as practically certain, but with respect to any 
 particular throw taken by itself, there is no way of telling in ad- 
 vance whether heads or tails will appear. This truth has been 
 worked out and applied most definitely to life insurance, but in 
 other branches also an effort is made to gather sufficient data that 
 will make possible the formulation of statistical laws as a guide 
 for future business. 
 
 Origin and Development. Arrangements embodying the idea 
 of insurance are found among the ancients, but the modern in- 
 stitution of insurance, although its origin is obscure, first becomes 
 prominent in the loans on bottomry which became common during 
 the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries. A loan on bottomry 
 meant that money was borrowed by the owner of a ship and was 
 to be repaid with interest at the termination of the voyage, but 
 the principal and interest were not to be repaid if the ship 
 was lost. Sometimes this took the form of insuring the captain's 
 life, but no scientific system of life insurance appeared until the 
 compilation of life tables. 
 
 Fire insurance received an impetus from the Great Fire of 
 London in 1666, the first company organized upon strict mer- 
 cantile principles being the Fire Office, organized in 1680. It 
 had a brigade of its own to prevent and extinguish fires. In 
 1693 Edmund Halley made a report to the Royal Society regard- 
 ing the mortality at various ages upon the basis of tables of births
 
 INSURANCE 487 
 
 and funerals at the city of Breslau, but practically, life insurance 
 as a business dates from the organization of the " Old Equitable" 
 in 1762. 
 
 Before this, however, there were many associations for conducting in- 
 surance upon a speculative basis, which entered into wagers of every con- 
 ceivable description. "Even the morality of the newspapers of that day 
 was shocked by such proceedings: we find the London Chronicle of 1768 
 thus declaiming, ' The introduction and amazing progress of illicit gaming 
 at Lloyd's Coffee-house is, among others, a powerful and very melancholy 
 proof of the degeneracy of the time. Though gaming in any degree is per- 
 verting the original and useful design of that Coffee-house, it may in some 
 measure be excusable to speculate on the following subjects: Mr. Wilkes 
 being elected member for London; -which was done from 5 to 50 guineas 
 per cent. ; Mr. Wilkes being elected member for Middlesex, from 20 to 
 70 guineas per cent; Alderman Bond's life/or one year, now doing at 7 per 
 cent; On Sir J. H. [mark the modesty] being turned out in one year, now 
 doing at 12 guineas per cent; On John Wilkes' life for one year, now 
 doing at five per cent. N.B. Warranted to remain in prison during that 
 period; On a declaration of war with France or Spain in one year, 8 
 guineas per cent. But,' continues the sensitive journalist, 'when policies 
 come to be opened on two of the first peers in Britain losing their heads 
 at IQS. 6d. per cent, or on the dissolution of the present parliament within 
 one year at 5 guineas per cent., which are now actually doing, and under- 
 written chiefly by Scotsmen, at the above Coffee-house, it is surely high time 
 to interfere.' " l 
 
 In the United States, fire insurance was fairly well begun even 
 in pre-revolutionary days. In 1830 was organized the New York 
 Life and Trust Company, and twelve years later appeared the 
 Mutual Life Insurance Company of New York, which is the oldest 
 of the existing life insurance companies which insure more than 
 a restricted class of individuals. Tables I and II show the growth 
 of life, fire, and marine insurance in the United States. A decline 
 in the number and importance of life companies appears in the 
 seventies. The numerous failures of this period brought the 
 "old line" life insurance into discredit, and in the following 
 years this fact, together with the desire for cheap insurance, caused 
 a marked development of assessment insurance, against which 
 there has in turn been a reaction because of its unscientific basis. 
 Recently the "old line" companies have again suffered a loss of 
 1 Walford, The Insurance Guide and Handbook, 4th ed., p. 27.
 
 488 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 TABLE I 
 
 NUMBER OF POLICIES AND AMOUNT OF INSURANCE IN FORCE IN ORDI- 
 NARY AND INDUSTRIAL COMPANIES, 1850 TO 1905 l 
 
 ORDINARY 
 
 INDUSTRIAL 
 
 Year 
 
 Number of 
 Policies 
 
 Amount (Dollars) 
 
 Number of 
 Policies 
 
 Amount (Dollars) 
 
 i8<CO . 
 
 29,407 
 60,000 
 839,226 
 679,690 
 890,924 
 1,319.561 
 1,940,945 
 3. 1 76,o5i 
 5.621,417 
 
 68,614,189 
 180,000,000 
 2,262,847,000 
 1,564,183,532 
 
 2 > I 55>33,627 
 3,620,057,439 
 4,917,694,131 
 7,093,152,380 
 11,054,255,524 
 
 
 
 i860 
 
 
 
 1870 . 
 
 
 
 1880 
 
 236,674 
 
 I ,377> 1 5 
 3,883,529 
 
 6,952-757 
 11,219,296 
 16,872,583 
 
 20,533,469 
 145,938,241 
 429,521,128 
 820,740,641 
 1,468,986,366 
 2,309,754,253 
 
 188-; . 
 
 1890 
 
 iSot; . 
 
 
 IOOC 
 
 
 TABLE II 
 FIRE, MARINE, AND CASUALTY INSURANCE, 1890-1905 l 
 
 FIRE AND MARINE (STOCK AND MUTUAL) 
 
 Year 
 
 Number 
 of com- 
 panies 
 
 Total income 
 
 Payments to 
 policy holders 
 
 Number 
 of com- 
 panies 
 
 Total income 
 
 Payments 
 to policy 
 holders 
 
 
 
 Dollars 
 
 Dollars 
 
 
 Dollars 
 
 Dollars 
 
 1890 . . . 
 
 580 
 
 I57, 8 57,983 
 
 80,768,012 
 
 34 
 
 9,758,413 
 
 2,933,306 
 
 1892 . . . 
 
 491 
 
 179,044,675 
 
 104,864,902 
 
 49 
 
 12,727,576 
 
 4,063,374 
 
 1893 . . . 
 
 489 
 
 178,971,022 
 
 114,652,625 
 
 46 
 
 15,140,830 
 
 4,815,298 
 
 1894 . . . 
 
 558 
 
 176,364,638 
 
 100,919,134 
 
 41 
 
 14,238,564 
 
 4,601,207 
 
 1895 . . . 
 
 583 
 
 176,300,042 
 
 97,379.026 
 
 47 
 
 18,077,146 
 
 5,430,607 
 
 1896 . . . 
 
 541 
 
 172,945,625 
 
 89,903,460 
 
 5 
 
 20,154,235 
 
 6,494,944 
 
 1897 . . . 
 
 53 
 
 i7 6 ,75 I - I2 4 
 
 87,165,252 
 
 53 
 
 22,859,866 
 
 7,113,818 
 
 1898 . . . 
 
 54 
 
 178,320,217 
 
 97,974,682 
 
 54 
 
 23,478,642 
 
 7,5 8 3>54i 
 
 1899 . . . 
 
 484 
 
 184,142,217 
 
 114,619,372 
 
 59 
 
 27, II 7>449 
 
 8,802,777 
 
 1900 . . . 
 
 493 
 
 198,312,577 
 
 116,753,281 
 
 62 
 
 32,309,619 
 
 10,166,796 
 
 1901 . . . 
 
 482 
 
 216,452,381 
 
 121,020,924 
 
 67 
 
 39,844,427 
 
 12,966,145 
 
 1902 . . . 
 
 489 
 
 239,468,206 
 
 123,332,012 
 
 67 
 
 43,980,061 
 
 14,952,568 
 
 1903 . . . 
 
 563 
 
 261,431,401 
 
 125,434,065 
 
 73 
 
 49,716,644 
 
 16,679,975 
 
 1904 . . . 
 
 55 
 
 281,228,402 
 
 165,658,558 
 
 82 
 
 55,685,447 
 
 I 9.332,539 
 
 1905 . . . 
 
 612 
 
 296,562,588 
 
 140,825,191 
 
 95 
 
 63,190,680 
 
 21,646,844 
 
 CASUALTY AND MISCELLANEOUS 
 
 1 See Statistical Abstract of the United States (annual) and The Insurance Year Books 
 published annually by the Spectator Company, New York, N.Y.
 
 INSURANCE 489 
 
 prestige on account of the scandalous extravagance and corrup- 
 tion revealed by official investigations. The evil practices had 
 to do chiefly with the management of the surplus, which was not 
 under legal control as was the reserve. These terms will be ex- 
 plained presently. It is probable that they will now learn the 
 lesson of economy, just as they have learned from their experience 
 a generation ago the supreme need of being solvent. Insurance 
 has grown until the insurance companies rival the banks in 
 financial importance. The assets of the leading life insurance 
 companies are nearly equal to the capital and deposits of all 
 national banks. 
 
 Forms of Insurance Organization. Fire insurance may be 
 written by stock companies, by mutual companies, or by associa- 
 tions of individual insurers, known as underwriters and Lloyds. 
 Mutual companies, again, may be either local county or town* 
 mutuals, state or general mutuals, or the manufacturers' mutuals. 
 The local town mutuals have the advantage that they can be 
 conducted with a very low cost of administration, but the business 
 of fire insurance seems best adapted to the stock companies, since 
 it is desirable that the risk of a conflagration should be spread 
 over a very wide territory. 
 
 Life companies are also found both in the stock and mutual 
 form. Theoretically the management of the latter is in the hands 
 of the policy holders themselves, but in actual practice they must 
 be managed by a small group of financiers. Attempts have been 
 made by recent legislation in some states to make the manage- 
 ment more nearly representative of the interests of the policy 
 holders by providing for election of officers by mail. Life in- 
 surance companies are also classified according to the plans of 
 premium payments: (i) "old line" level premium, (2) assessment, 
 (3) stipulated premium, and (4) fraternal orders. 
 
 Wherever risk enters in modern life, companies are organized 
 to offer an escape from it through insurance even before 
 enough data have been collected to make possible the accurate 
 prediction of the amount of loss. In addition to life insurance 
 we have indemnity in case of sickness, accident, destruction by 
 fire, wind, hail, explosions of boilers or fly wheels, broken windows,
 
 490 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 and loss from burglary or the unfaithfulness of employees. Li- 
 ability insurance in over a dozen different forms guards against 
 loss from damage suits. It is impossible to take up the problems 
 that are peculiar to each one of these branches, but we note the 
 leading features of the most important branch in life insurance. 
 
 LIFE INSURANCE 
 
 Life Tables. A life table or mortality table shows how many 
 of a large group of persons of the same age will survive to each 
 higher age. A number of these tables have been calculated, 
 but the one generally used in this country is the American Ex- 
 perience Mortality table, a portion of which is here reproduced : 
 
 AGE 
 
 LIVING AT BEGINNING OF YEAR 
 
 DYING DURING THE YEAR 
 
 10 
 
 IOO,OOO 
 
 749 
 
 it 
 
 99.251 
 
 746 
 
 12 
 
 98,505 
 
 743 
 
 13 
 
 97,762 
 
 740 
 
 14 
 
 97,022 
 
 737 
 
 15 
 
 96,285 
 
 735 
 
 16 
 
 95.55 
 
 732 
 
 17 
 
 94,818 
 
 729 
 
 18 
 
 94,089 
 
 727 
 
 J 9 
 
 93,362 
 
 725 
 
 * 
 
 * 
 
 * 
 
 90 
 
 847 
 
 385 
 
 9 1 
 
 462 
 
 246 
 
 92 
 
 216 
 
 137 
 
 93 
 
 79 
 
 58 
 
 94 
 
 21 
 
 18 
 
 95 
 
 3 
 
 3 
 
 With such data and with an assumed rate of interest and ex- 
 penses, it is possible to say with considerable certainty how much 
 money must be collected from the policy holders in order to pay 
 each one $1000 or other sum at death. 
 
 Premium Plans. It would be possible to collect from those 
 surviving at each age enough money to pay for the deaths that
 
 INSURANCE 491 
 
 would happen during the ensuing year. This step rate plan 
 would mean in the later years of the table a larger and larger 
 assessment ; that is, at the time when the earning power of the 
 insured was declining. It has become customary to arrange the 
 payments on what is known as the level premium plan, the same 
 annual payment being made throughout the life of the policy. 
 This payment may be on the ordinary life plan, that is, the pay- 
 ments continue throughout life; or ten, fifteen, or twenty limited 
 payments may be made, the policy continuing in force for life; 
 or the insurance may be for only a term of years during which the 
 premiums are paid, the insurance ceasing entirely at the end of 
 the term. This is the cheapest kind of insurance, for the insurance 
 company knows that many of the insured will survive beyond the 
 term, and to them no payment need be made, but when the in- 
 surance continues for life, the payment becomes a certainty in 
 every case. 
 
 The Reserve. If a level premium is charged, the income of 
 the company in the earlier years exceeds its current mortality 
 requirements. The portions of the premium not currently used 
 must be held for the credit of the policy holders until the later 
 years, a certain rate of interest being allowed. This accumulating 
 fund is known as the reserve. 
 
 Surplus. If the insured die less rapidly than was assumed 
 by the company in calculating its premiums, more money will 
 be collected than is necessary to meet the obligations of the in- 
 surance contracts. This is one source of surplus. Again, the 
 funds held in trust by the company may be invested at a higher 
 rate of interest than was assumed in the calculations, and this is 
 a second source of surplus. A third source of surplus is in keep- 
 ing expenses below what was assumed in the calculations. (The 
 addition which is made to the net premium to cover expenses is 
 called "loading," and is commonly not far from a third of the net 
 premium.) The amounts paid in by those who lapse or surrender 
 their policies do not all go to the surplus, for it is customary now 
 to allow surrender values and paid-up insurance, but as these 
 values are subject to a surrender charge, there is an addition to 
 the surplus from the surrendered or lapsed policies, although the
 
 492 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 companies try to discourage lapsing. Out of this surplus are 
 paid the dividends on the capital stock, if there be any, and 
 the dividends to each policy holder, which in some cases are 
 credited or paid annually to each policy holder, or in other cases 
 not until the expiration of a period of years. 
 
 Endowments. What is ordinarily called an endowment 
 policy is a combination of two distinct forms of contract. A 
 simple life insurance contract promises to pay the insured a certain 
 sum in the event of death; a pure endowment contract would pay 
 a certain sum if the holder of the policy survives after a period 
 of years. A twenty-year so-called "endowment" policy com- 
 bining these two features means that payment would be made 
 at death if that occurred within the twenty years, or at the expira- 
 tion of twenty years if the policy holder survives. 
 
 This form of policy has been declining in popularity because 
 in its ordinary form it is disadvantageous to the policy holder, 
 unless he be so thriftless that he cannot be induced to save in any 
 other way; also, if insurance could not be obtained in any other 
 way, it might be wise to purchase such a policy, but the objects 
 of saving and insuring can be more cheaply accomplished by 
 separating the two features. If, instead of paying $50 for an 
 endowment policy, the holder paid part of this for term insurance 
 and put the remainder in a savings bank at three or four per cent 
 compound interest, there might be more to his credit whether 
 he lived or died. But when the loading is properly arranged, 
 and with an annual distribution of surplus, the endowment policy 
 performs a useful function as an encouragement of thrift. In 
 fact, a very long term endowment maturing at, say, age sixty-five, 
 would best meet the needs of a great many persons. 
 
 These points will be made clearer by the following illustration 
 of what becomes of the premium in the case of a ten-year endow- 
 ment policy at age thirty-five with a premium of $107.70, when 
 it is assumed that the mortality will be in accordance with the 
 American Experience Table, that the company will earn three 
 per cent on its funds, and that the expense charged each year to 
 this policy will be as given in the following table : l 
 
 1 Report of the Wisconsin Joint Legislative Investigating Committee, 1906, 
 P- iS3-
 
 INSURANCE 
 
 493 
 
 POLICY YEAR 
 
 EXPENSE CHARGE 
 
 MORTALITY CHARGE 
 
 DEPOSIT 
 
 I 
 
 $18.40 
 
 $7.96 
 
 $81.34 
 
 2 
 
 18.40 
 
 7-31 
 
 165.77 
 
 3 
 
 18.40 
 
 6.62 
 
 253-42 
 
 4 
 
 18.40 
 
 S-89 
 
 344-43 
 
 5 
 
 18.40 
 
 5.10 
 
 438.96 
 
 6 
 
 18.40 
 
 4.26 
 
 537-17 
 
 7 
 
 18.40 
 
 3-32 
 
 639.27 
 
 8 
 
 18.40 
 
 2.32 
 
 745-43 
 
 9 
 
 18.40 
 
 1. 21 
 
 855-89 
 
 10 
 
 18.40 
 
 
 970.87 
 
 Totals 
 
 184.00 
 
 43-99 
 
 
 Industrial Insurance. The business of insuring the lives of 
 workingmen in this country is characterized by the small amount 
 of the average policy, the large number of lapses, and the heavy 
 expense of solicitation. These companies say the workingman 
 is so thriftless that it is necessary to collect the premiums through 
 a house to house canvass by agents. The hesitancy shown by 
 workingmen to insure in these companies is considered by some 
 persons, however, as an evidence of their thrift. Which is the 
 correct view will be shown by the results of an experiment which 
 is now being tried in the state of Massachusetts. Savings banks 
 have been authorized to organize insurance departments and to 
 sell life insurance, but without employing paid agents or solicitors. 
 The workingman is expected to go to the bank of his own accord. 
 The whole system is supervised by a State Actuary and a State 
 Medical Director, and the safety of the plan is assured by a guaran- 
 tee fund. Three forms of policies, limited to $500, are provided 
 for: ordinary life insurance, endowment, and a combination of 
 life insurance and old-age annuity. This plan may prove to be 
 a solution of the problem of old age pensions. 
 
 State Insurance. Insurance is well adapted to direct manage- 
 ment by the State because the actual conduct of the business is 
 of a relatively simple and routine character and because the State 
 can offer greater security and can command greater confidence
 
 494 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 than is possible in the case of a private corporation. Competi- 
 tion has had the effect of causing rival companies to invent many 
 outwardly attractive combinations of policy conditions, but on 
 the whole it has increased rather than decreased the expense of 
 doing the business. When the State enters the field simply as an 
 additional competitor, as in New Zealand, its full advantage is 
 not apparent ; but if it has a monopoly of the business and com- 
 pels every one to insure, it perhaps can, without any selection of 
 risks, effect the insurance at a lower price than is asked by any 
 existing private company. 1 These considerations, however, can 
 hardly be taken as sufficient arguments for the present assump- 
 tion of insurance functions by the State. 
 
 State Regulation. Following the example of Massachusetts 
 in 1858, other states have appointed insurance commissioners 
 for the supervision of this business, and the insurance laws of 
 a single one of these states are now sufficient to make a good- 
 sized volume. Insurance companies have found this variety of 
 control irksome and have generally advocated federal control of 
 insurance. Although something would be gained, it cannot be 
 said that there is any great need of federal control of life insurance, 
 not to mention the constitutional difficulties, because it is not 
 absolutely necessary, as in transportation or fire insurance, that 
 one life company do business in many states, and the people of 
 each state should have the right to say what kind of insurance 
 institutions they desire to have. 
 
 An enumeration of the requirements in the state of New York 
 will illustrate the nature of state regulation: A certificate of 
 authorization must be obtained from the Superintendent of 
 Insurance and a deposit of securities must be made. A minimum 
 capital stock is prescribed and regulations are made concerning 
 the investment of stock and surplus. There are also provisions 
 relating to standard of solvency, reinsurance, limitation of risks, 
 admission of foreign companies, examination of accounts, and 
 annual reports. The policy must contain the entire contract, 
 and the statements are to be taken as representations and not 
 
 1 Consult the article by M. M. Dawson in Bliss, Encyclopedia of Social Reform, 
 new ed.
 
 INSURANCE 495 
 
 warranties. No misleading estimates and deceptive statements 
 are to be issued for the purpose of getting business. Life insur- 
 ance companies are to do either a participating or non-par- 
 ticipating business, and in the former case the surplus must be 
 annually apportioned and paid to each policy. There are further 
 provisions regarding the valuation of policies, surrender values, 
 discrimination, election of directors, limitation of the amount of 
 new business each year, limitations as to expenses and salaries of 
 officers, and standard forms of policies are prescribed for both life 
 and fire insurance. 1 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. How do you define insurance? 
 
 2. What is a mortality table? 
 
 3. How would you find the premium for insuring a group of persons for 
 one year for $1000 each? 
 
 4. Distinguish between reserve and surplus. 
 
 5. What is a "pure" endowment policy? 
 
 6. What are the advantages and objections of assessment insurance? 
 
 7. What has been New Zealand's experience with State insurance? 
 
 8. What is meant by the " moral hazard " ? 
 
 9. What are tontine policies? 
 
 10. Discuss life insurance investments. 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ALEXANDER, WILLIAM. The Life Insurance Company. 
 
 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science (a series 
 
 of articles), Vol. XXVI. 
 DAWSON, M. M. The Elements of Life Insurance and The Business of 
 
 Life Insurance. 
 
 FRICKE, WILLIAM A. (Compiler). Insurance A Text-book. 
 Gow, WILLIAM. Marine Insurance. 
 Institute of Actuaries, Text-book. 
 
 KITCHIN, F. H. The Principles and Finance of Fire Insurance. 
 MOIR, HENRY. Life Assurance Primer. 
 
 New York Insurance Investigating Committee, Report, 1905, 6 vols. 
 " Q. P." How to buy Life Insurance. 
 WAMBAUGH, EUGENE. A Selection of Cases on Insurance. 
 Yale Insurance Lectures, 1903-1904, 2 vols. 
 WALFORD, CORNELIUS. The Insurance Guide and Handbook. 
 Wisconsin Insurance Investigating Committee, Report, 1906. 
 ZARTMAN, L. W. The Investments of Life Insurance Companies. 
 
 1 See Parker, A. J., Jr., The Insurance Law of New York, New York, 1907.
 
 CHAPTER XXIX 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 
 
 Importance of Municipal Activity. Far reaching as are the 
 economic activities of the state and federal governments, they are 
 surpassed in magnitude, if not in importance, by the similar ac- 
 tivities of the municipal governments. Finance statistics furnish 
 a rough measure of the scope of such functions. In 1902, for ex- 
 ample, the public debt of the cities, villages, and towns ($1,387,- 
 316,976) was greater than the public debt of the county, territo- 
 rial, state, and national governments combined ($1,356,485,129). 
 The local administrative divisions, moreover, including counties, 
 collect and spend more money year by year than the state and na- 
 tional governments; and taking into account the fact that munici- 
 pal functions are to a much greater degree economic than the 
 functions of the national government, it is probable that the cities 
 having more than 8000 inhabitants in 1902, with their current 
 expenditures of $551,234,172, really spent more for distinctively 
 economic purposes than the national government, with current 
 expenditures of $617,530,137. 
 
 By the use of financial statistics, moreover, we may obtain a 
 rough idea of the relative importance of the economic as compared 
 with the political or social activities of the cities themselves. Re- 
 cent census bulletins have distinguished the commercial or quasi- 
 economic receipts of cities from the general revenue receipts. In 
 1902 these commercial receipts constituted 22 per cent of all the 
 revenues in cities containing over 25,000 inhabitants, and 20.7 per 
 cent of the total revenues in cities containing over 8000 but less 
 than 25,000 inhabitants. These figures establish a fair inference 
 that as municipalities increase in size, a larger and larger share of 
 the public activity is devoted to economic services. The same 
 
 496
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 497 
 
 phenomenon appears in the total state, county, and municipal 
 finances of the different sections of the country. Taking the coun- 
 try as a whole and considering all revenues except those received 
 by the national government, 15.6 per cent are derived from com- 
 mercial sources. In New England, with its high proportion of 
 urban residents, 20.6 per cent of the aggregate revenues are com- 
 mercial; in the South Central division, with its low percentage of 
 urban population, only 13.3 per cent are commercial. Generally 
 speaking, the economic activities of the State vary directly as the 
 density of the population. 
 
 Commonplace as such a conclusion may be, it carries with it, 
 nevertheless, a profound significance. City life means crowding, 
 and crowding means greater social friction or greater social soli- 
 darity, according as the State fails or succeeds in its task of devis- 
 ing rules by which the swarming city masses may live together, 
 not only in peace and concord, but to better advantage and with 
 greater profit. In the preceding pages we have emphasized again 
 and again the necessity for increased regulation on the part of the 
 State. Many factors cooperate to justify this thesis. But the 
 most powerful factor of all is created by the simple interplay of 
 two economic facts, whose importance can never be overestimated 
 the growth of urban or semi-urban populations, and the com- 
 parative fixity of the territory upon which those populations must 
 dwell and work. 
 
 If the position taken above be correct, we have only to glance 
 at the steadily swelling population of our cities to understand why 
 State control either through regulation or ownership must increase. 
 In 1800, four inhabitants out of every one hundred dwelt in a 
 city containing 8000 inhabitants or more. In 1900, thirty-three 
 out of ever)' one hundred inhabitants dwelt in cities of this descrip- 
 tion. And the movement to the cities still continues. In the 
 states taking an interdecennial census, in 1905, 48.5 per cent of 
 the total population dwelt in the incorporated places having 8000 
 inhabitants or more (in 1900), while only 45.8 percent of the popu- 
 lation dwelt in the same places in 1900. The increase of the gen- 
 eral population of these states between 1900 and 1905 was 9.2 
 per cent; the increase of their urban population as above defined
 
 498 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 was 15.2 per cent. In some states, and these perhaps most typical 
 of present tendencies, a large majority of the entire population 
 dwelt in cities of 8000 inhabitants or more, the proportion in 1905 
 reaching 71.7 per cent in New York, 67.4 per cent in Massachusetts, 
 and 66.4 per cent in Rhode Island. Even in Illinois, a typical 
 state of our greatest agricultural region, more than half the popu- 
 lation dwelt in such cities, according to census estimates, in 1906. 
 To-day the city of New York contains a larger population than did 
 the whole United States at the beginning of Washington's first 
 administration; it spends more money than the national govern- 
 ment did at any time previous to the Civil War; and its annual 
 budget largely surpasses in amount that of Turkey, Portugal, Aus- 
 tria-Hungary, China, Holland, Norway, or Sweden. 
 
 Character of Municipal Activities. But there is another and a 
 more important reason why the activities of the State must multi- 
 ply and become increasingly economic as a larger and larger pro- 
 portion of the population make their homes in the cities. The 
 mere agglomeration of people in a restricted locality creates a vast 
 fund of wealth, which occupies, as it increases, a larger and larger 
 share of the public attention. Land values go up, the streets of the 
 city acquire enormous value, the opportunities of serving the dense 
 city population in a variety of ways multiply; in short, the public 
 domain of the city is enormously enhanced in value, and the city 
 government is forced to give more and more thought to its proper 
 exploitation and development. The typical economic problem of 
 the modern city is summed up in the one word " franchise "; and 
 the municipal franchise is largely a product of mere agglomera- 
 tion. 
 
 This fund of franchise values has perhaps done more than any- 
 thing else to transform the character of city government. Where 
 the people in their collective capacity have little or no property 
 and are forced to raise all public revenue by taxation, there is 
 likely to be not only a passive and fitful interest in public affairs, 
 but the activity of the government is equally apt to be comprised 
 within very narrow limits. Give the people, however, a public 
 treasure to preserve, a patrimony to protect, valuable franchises 
 to guard from pillage, and exploit for the public profit, and their
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 499 
 
 interest is aroused. The public by very necessity is forced to 
 abandon its old attitude of laissez-faire, and do something more 
 than maintain a balance between private interests through its 
 police and courts. It becomes a proprietor; its household, its 
 property, its bank account grow; its interests become more and 
 more economic. 
 
 " In earlier days, even the most elementary public functions were performed 
 by the individual. He paved, cleaned, and lighted the street before his door. 
 He was his own constable. Such health protection as he enjoyed was the 
 result of his own vigilance. Education was conducted at home or by the 
 church. The library was a priestly possession, as was all learning. His 
 house was his castle, even in the midst of the city, and society offered him 
 little save the administration of justice and protection from foreign foes. 
 
 "To-day the city protects his life and his property from injury. It safe- 
 guards his health in countless ways. It cleans and lights his streets, collects 
 his garbage, supplies him with employees through free employment bureaus. 
 It educates his children, supplies them with books, and in many instances 
 with food. It offers him a library, and through the opening of branches 
 almost brings it to his door. It offers nature in the parks ; supplies him with 
 opportunities for recreation and pleasure through concerts, lectures, and the 
 like. It maintains a public market; administers justice; supplies nurses, 
 physicians, and hospital service, as well as a cemetery for burial. It takes 
 the refuse from his door and brings back water, gas, and frequently heat and 
 power at the same time. It inspects his food, protects his life and that of his 
 children through public oversight of the conditions of factory labor. It 
 safeguards him from contagious disease, facilitates communication upon the 
 streets, and in some instances offers opportunities for higher technical and 
 professional education." * 
 
 We have cited this striking passage in order to bring home viv- 
 idly to the mind of the reader the fact that the modern city is a 
 vast household, with human wants and interests similar to those 
 which on a more restricted scale absorb the interests of the ordi- 
 nary householder. It is important, however, to look briefly at 
 municipal activities in a somewhat more prosaic way. If we 
 classify the functions commonly assumed by municipalities either 
 in this country or Europe, paying more attention to the newer 
 and more debatable functions, because it is these which give 
 rise to real problems, we find that they fall naturally into the 
 following groups: I. First, the protective Junctions, brought to 
 1 Frederic C. Howe, The City the Hope of Democracy, pp. 28, 29.
 
 500 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 mind by the police, the courts, the fire department. II. Secondly, 
 those activities devoted to sanitation and the public health. These 
 functions, which are exceedingly various, are represented by mu- 
 nicipal ownership of slaughterhouses, ice factories, baths, laun- 
 dries, model tenements, cemeteries, sewers, by municipal garbage 
 removal, street cleaning, hospitals, nurses and doctors, and in a 
 few cities even by the ownership and control of taverns and sa- 
 loons. III. Charities and corrections. This group comprehends 
 not only the almshouses and jails, but the labor colonies and 
 pawn shops which are maintained in a few European cities. 
 IV. Educational and cultural; for example, schools, parks, li- 
 braries, and museums. V. The activities included in this group 
 are commercial and developmental. The educational functions 
 are of course developmental; but the markets, docks, harbors, 
 streets, bridges, employment and statistical bureaus included in 
 this group are maintained more for the purpose of developing 
 industry and trade than the human mind and faculties. VI. 
 Municipal monopolies; e.g. water, gas, electric lighting, street 
 railway, telephone companies, and the like. 
 
 Before considering the unsettled municipal problems which 
 center chiefly around the activities classified in V and VI, let us 
 examine briefly the characteristics of the more economic and com- 
 mercial functions which have been generally assumed by Ameri- 
 can municipalities. Wharves and docks, ferries and quays, have 
 been acquired and their operation undertaken by the public, be- 
 cause trade and commerce, in general, the whole business of the 
 city, are intimately dependent upon their proper management in 
 the public interest, while at the same time they give rise to no 
 intricate technical or administrative problems. Much the same 
 characteristics mark highways, bridges, and canals. A few years 
 ago many of the highways were privately owned. The State took 
 them over, because the payment of tolls was exceedingly incon- 
 venient and hampered commerce, because the question of price 
 or profit was insignificant in comparison with the general public 
 importance of free communication, and because the management 
 of highways and bridges is comparatively easy and simple. Water- 
 works likewise are owned and satisfactorily managed by most of
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 50! 
 
 the larger American municipalities. Here again the reasons are 
 clear. As in the case of streets and roads, the public health and 
 convenience are so overwhelmingly important in this connection 
 that the question of price and profit becomes of secondary impor- 
 tance, while the operation of the industry itself is simple and easy, 
 although the installation of the plant may acquire enormous capi- 
 tal and great engineering skill. 
 
 All these quasi-commercial undertakings, then, which have been 
 generally assumed by American municipalities are characterized 
 by five important qualities: (a) all of them are natural monopo- 
 lies ; (b) the interest of practically the whole community is vi- 
 tally dependent upon their proper operation ; (c) because they 
 touch the consumer and taxpayer so constantly, the quality of 
 the service is incessantly subjected to the criticism of taxpayers 
 and voters; (d) in all of them profit and price per unit of service 
 are secondary considerations, wholly outweighed by larger con- 
 siderations of public health or convenience, and (e) all of them 
 possess the " invariable routine-like character " which Jevons 
 mentions, and are capable of operation by simple, general rules. 
 
 The Present Problem. These five criteria of public industries 
 may be used affirmatively, but not negatively; i.e. it is logical to 
 conclude that any industry which possesses these qualifications 
 may with safety be assumed by the public, but it is illogical to 
 infer that any industry which does not possess all of them must 
 be left to private management. Indeed, the burning question of 
 to-day is just this: whether street railways which are not easily 
 managed, and lighting plants or telephone systems which are nei- 
 ther capable of operation by simple rules nor so vitally connected 
 with the public welfare as water companies or streets and bridges, 
 should be municipalized. Before discussing municipal owner- 
 ship and management, however, it is necessary to consider the 
 alternatives which have been suggested. 
 
 Protection through Competition. We mention the discarded 
 idea that good service and reasonable prices will be secured by 
 the pressure of competition, merely to emphasize the progress that 
 has been made in the past few years. A generation ago, the be- 
 lief was still prevalent that competition would protect the public
 
 502 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 from extortion. To-day, it is everywhere admitted that the public 
 industries which we are discussing are municipal monopolies above 
 and beyond competitive control. Consolidation of competing 
 companies is the recognized rule. Practically all the street rail- 
 way lines have been brought under one control in Brooklyn, Balti- 
 more, Boston, Philadelphia, Buffalo, Cincinnati, Pittsburg; and 
 in other cities where the control is not absolutely unified, there 
 are likely to be only two or three systems and these working in 
 harmony and cooperation. In 1890 more than three fourths of 
 the street railway companies had less than ten miles of line, and 
 together such small lines represented more than two fifths of 
 the total mileage of the country. In 1902, however, less than 
 half of the companies operated less than ten miles of line, and in 
 all, such small lines represented less than one eighth of the total 
 mileage. In 1890, moreover, only two companies had lines ex- 
 ceeding one hundred miles in length, and their combined mileage 
 was less than one twentieth of the total. In 1892, twenty -five 
 railways exceeded this limit, and together they embraced more 
 than one fourth of the total mileage of the country. 1 
 
 Moreover, there has been a consolidation of ownership similar 
 to the consolidation of plants. Great syndicates have been 
 formed, which operate in many cities and often control the gas 
 and electric plants as well as the street railway systems. Such 
 combinations exist in Pittsburg, Baltimore, and many other 
 cities. "The Interstate Railways Company, which succeeded the 
 United Power and Transportation Company in 1902, controls 
 about fifteen street railway systems in Pennsylvania, New Jersey, 
 and Delaware, together with two electric light companies. It 
 has also acquired the stock and franchises of numerous new 
 railway companies. Some of the lines controlled are more or 
 less closely connected, and others may be brought into connec- 
 tion later, but the primary purpose has been, apparently, not so 
 much to make a single great system as to provide a convenient 
 form of investment. The American Railways Company of Phil- 
 adelphia controls eight or nine widely separated street railways 
 and lighting plants in Ohio, Illinois, New Jersey, and Penn- 
 
 1 Special Census Report, Street and Electric Railways, p. 121.
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 503 
 
 sylvania, and also a minority interest in the stock of the Chicago 
 Union Traction Company. The Railways Company General con- 
 trols stocks of seven railway lines, and lighting plants in New 
 York, Pennsylvania, and Michigan." l 
 
 The franchises now in the possession of these large combina- 
 tions are of enormous value. In the early part of this chapter 
 attention was called to the stupendous size of the American mu- 
 nicipal debt, amounting in 1902 to $1,387,316,976. The munici- 
 pal franchises now in possession of private corporations, accord- 
 ing to trustworthy computations, exceed in value the enormous 
 debt of our cities; so that if the latter had undertaken these serv- 
 ices themselves, managed them as efficiently as the private com- 
 panies, and charged the same prices, they would now possess 
 assets in excess of their fiscal obligations. Indeed, in many of 
 the larger cities of this country, the franchises of the street rail- 
 way companies alone exceed in value the whole municipal debt. 
 
 So rapid has the movement of monopoly been in the industries 
 under consideration, so deeply has the eager struggle for these 
 great franchise values corrupted city government, that one no 
 longer hears of regulation through competition. The private cor- 
 porations themselves admit to-day not only that services and prices 
 must be regulated by the public, but that their business must be 
 taken out of politics. The question has ceased to be: Shall pub- 
 lic utilities be controlled? It has become: Can they be controlled 
 by anything short of municipal ownership and management? 
 
 Methods of Public Regulation. The alternative most fre- 
 quently suggested is public regulation. There are many kinds 
 of regulation, and one of these we have had, potentially at least, 
 during the entire period in which our cities have been pillaged 
 and our municipal councils corrupted. All the time this has been 
 going on, the state legislatures have had the right to regulate, if 
 they saw fit; but they seldom saw fit. General regulation thus 
 amounts to nothing. Special methods and special machinery 
 must be devised, if regulation is to be made effective. 
 
 1 A description of the extent of such combinations together with other suggestive 
 details may be found in Chapter VIII of the Census Report, Street and Electric 
 Railways, from which the above quotation is taken.
 
 504 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The second method we may for brevity call the Commission 
 Method, although the mere fact that there is to be a commission 
 amounts to little, while the character of the men on the commis- 
 sion and the manner in which they are to conduct their regulation 
 amounts to a very great deal. Adequate regulation through a 
 commission, to our mind, contemplates the following specific pro- 
 visions: (a) That cities, at least of the larger size, shall be per- 
 mitted either to undertake and manage public utilities on their 
 own account, to sell or rent franchises on the best terms, or con- 
 demn and purchase under the power of eminent domain the 
 existing franchises and property of public utility companies pos- 
 sessing perpetual franchises; (b) that, whether under public or 
 private management, public utilities shall, so far as possible, be 
 strictly monopolized, or in other words, there shall hereafter be 
 no unnecessary duplication of plant for which consumers are forced 
 to pay; (c) that the service and charges of both public and pri- 
 vate plants shall be reasonable, any group (say of twenty-five con- 
 sumers) having the right to test such reasonableness before the 
 commission; (d) that to secure the necessary basis for a judg- 
 ment of what constitutes reasonableness, the commission shall 
 make a valuation of all public utilities; (e) and thereafter exer- 
 cise a strict control over extensions, improvements, and the issue 
 of new securities; (/) that the commission shall inspect the serv- 
 ice or products of public utility companies and shall introduce 
 a system of uniform accounting in both public and private com- 
 panies; (g) and publish annually, or at shorter periods, compara- 
 tive statistics of revenue, cost, and service, in order that the 
 efficiency of public and private service may be contrasted. 
 
 This last provision of publicity is exceedingly important. It 
 will not only spur both private and public companies to make as 
 good a record as possible, but will exercise a most wholesome 
 influence upon the commission itself. In Massachusetts, for ex- 
 ample, the Board of Gas and Electric Light Commissioners has 
 been severely censured in the past for its secrecy and failure to 
 publish the data by which a judgment could be rendered concern- 
 ing the reasonableness of the charges of private companies. " If 
 the Board," a prominent newspaper once said, '' is empowered to
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 505 
 
 keep secret what information it is pleased to, how are people to 
 know that they may not become a mere agency of the monopolies 
 to cover up and justify their possible undue exactions." With 
 publicity of a really adequate kind, this criticism never would 
 have been made. 
 
 An exceedingly important part of the scheme of regulation is 
 that just as many difficulties as possible shall be anticipated and 
 specifically arranged for in the original charter. Regulation thus 
 becomes largely an interpretation of accepted principles, not the 
 formulation of principles de novo. New York City, for instance, 
 used its credit to secure the construction of the subway and then 
 leased it to the Interborough Rapid Transit Company on such 
 terms that in fifty years the principal and interest of the debt will 
 have been paid, and the city will own the subway practically 
 without expense. Another illustration of the favorable terms 
 which a city may secure by careful bargaining is found in the 
 arrangement which the city of Chicago made in 1907 with the 
 Chicago City Railway and the Chicago Union Traction Company. 
 The companies not only agreed to rebuild and improve the whole 
 street railway system, to provide new through routes and addi- 
 tional transfers, and to operate under a license revocable at any 
 time by the city upon payment of the agreed value of the roads 
 plus the cost of improvements, but the city is to exercise a large 
 degree of control over the frequency of the service and supervise 
 rigidly the accounts of the company, while all profits above 5 
 per cent on the actual investment are to be shared between the 
 city and the railways, 55 per cent to the former and 45 per cent to 
 the latter. 1 
 
 We cite these examples partially to show that our cities are 
 gradually learning to drive better bargains with the corporations 
 than in the past, but principally to emphasize the fact that such 
 freedom of contract would be perfectly possible under the com- 
 mission form of regulation, and would at the same time facilitate 
 
 1 In speaking of these terms as "favorable," we merely mean more advanta- 
 geous to the city than has usually characterized the franchise grants of the past. 
 In this particular case it is possible that Chicago might have obtained even better 
 terms, or that municipal ownership and management might have been the wisest 
 solution of the problem.
 
 i a& JaxtmBiE tflai Ac
 
 I.' . .-,">'. -v ;:; : >- .. '.""-_ ::.: -,:- 
 
 19 
 
 'HEEL 
 
 :-:i viiu-i vi 
 
 .HUT" di ; 
 
 
 
 i. i 
 
 
 nm rr TWRH 
 
 rmnaMBBBaE^n 
 
 A DBS sft gmran 
 
 nTfSirfefniiinT 
 
 r-L L-- 
 
 i rr.' :; -v:.-. : - 
 -..:-. . ; ::_-.-:: :: 
 
 R die T?sute 
 nasEcntsTT 
 
 UllHTQlTIT. 
 
 V-- 
 
 .;-- 
 
 :- 
 -- 
 
 in lafK,,
 
 508 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 cities supplied more consumers and charged on the average lower 
 rates than the private companies. Similarly, in the United States, 
 a large majority of the water works are now owned by municipali- 
 ties, while in 1902 the municipalities owned 815 out of the 3620 
 central electrical stations, employing 2467 out of the 23,330 wage 
 earners employed, and supplying 195,904,439 out of the aggre- 
 gate 2,507,051,115 kilowatt hours of power. At first blush, it 
 would appear that the safest arguments for or against municipal 
 ownership might be derived from a comparative study of munici- 
 pal and private operation. Such, however, is not the case. Owing 
 to the predominating importance of technical questions in such 
 comparisons, none but expert engineers or accountants are com- 
 petent to draw conclusions, and unfortunately the conclusions of 
 the experts are in hopeless conflict. The expert representatives of 
 the private companies return from their study of public manage- 
 ment with their opinions unchanged; while the expert defendants 
 of municipal ownership find in the results of English or American 
 municipalization little but confirmation of their existing opin- 
 ions. In fact, we are forced back upon more or less general 
 considerations. 
 
 If we carefully examine the important arguments in favor of 
 municipal management, we shall find that many of them assume 
 that regulation of the character previously described is impossible, 
 (a) The most emphasis is placed by defendants of municipal 
 management upon the fact that private ownership in the past has 
 resulted in widespread political corruption. No one, to-day, de- 
 nies this truth. But never in the past have we attempted the kind 
 of regulation which we may expect in the future, and which has 
 already been started, though not perfected, in the states of New 
 York and Wisconsin. This species of regulation contemplates a 
 valuation of public and private plants, with prevention of stock 
 watering and reduction of profits to a reasonable level. If we 
 can sell or rent franchises (not give them away), prevent the capi- 
 talization of excessive profits, and keep dividends on a rational 
 basis, the raison d'etre of bribery and corruption disappears. 
 Corporations cannot afford to pay bribes for the opportunity of 
 earning reasonable profits.
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 
 
 509 
 
 (6) The second great argument for municipal management is 
 that it will improve the public service by increasing its extent, 
 dignity, and importance. This position is probably well taken. 
 The supreme necessity for judicial purity has given us pure courts. 
 The supreme necessity for decent management of public utilities, 
 if they were undertaken by our municipal governments, would, 
 it is probable, give us decent management. Certainly, at least, 
 every one agrees that it would be suicidal to introduce municipal 
 management without putting it on a civil service basis. 
 
 (c) The next characteristic of public industry is as often cited 
 against as in favor of municipal management. Except for high- 
 class salaried men, where the reverse is true, the State treats its 
 employees unusually well, paying larger wages for shorter hours 
 of labor than most private employers. This will appear as a vir- 
 tue or defect, according to our viewpoint. If we believe that 
 the State should be a model employer, and pay fair living wages 
 whether private employers do so or not, this characteristic of 
 municipal management will appear as a strong reason for its 
 introduction. If, on the other hand, we concentrate our thoughts 
 on cheapness of production, and neglect all considerations of the 
 welfare of the producers, we must score a point under this head 
 in favor of private operation. 
 
 (d) One of the strongest charges against municipal ownership 
 is based upon the fairness and humanity which the State shows 
 in dealing with its employees. It is charged that such treatment 
 tends to corrupt the public servant, and to destroy his political 
 independence, making him a subservient henchman and sup- 
 porter of the administration under which he happens to be work- 
 ing. That there is danger of such "pernicious activity" on the 
 part of office holders, no reasonable student of public affairs will 
 deny. In the recent Chicago city campaign, when, as it happened, 
 municipal ownership was the burning issue, the head of the police 
 department attempted, and partially succeeded, in forcing almost 
 the entire police force to work for the election of one of the can- 
 didates. But this candidate was defeated, despite the police, 
 and the police official is at the present writing under criminal 
 indictment.
 
 510 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 This rebuke of police interference is of crucial import. It calls 
 attention to the fact that American voters have learned to resent 
 such interference. In scores of city elections in the last five years 
 the independent political sense of the people has triumphed over 
 office-holding cliques who attempted to perpetuate their sway; 
 and not only has the electorate shown its ability to control the 
 office holders, but with every year it has become more and more 
 difficult for political bosses to dictate to the office holders them- 
 selves. Without civil service, of course, municipal management is 
 unworthy of consideration. With it, however, the whole sting of 
 this criticism vanishes. Not only will public employees cease to 
 be of one political faith, but the better conditions of employment 
 offered by the State will probably cease to make a petty grafter 
 of the public employee. The reason for the last statement is 
 plain. If the State pays $4.00 a day for carpenters, while private 
 employers offer but $3.00, the $1.00 difference may have either 
 of two effects: under the spoils system, it will go to indifferent 
 or average workmen in the form of a pauperizing bounty; but 
 under the merit system, it will bring to the State the best skill 
 in the occupation. Better conditions of employment, where 
 the merit system prevails, merely "concentrate competition upon 
 efficiency." 
 
 Moreover, it may be remarked that it is not open to opponents 
 of municipal ownership to assert that: "all this argument pre- 
 supposes appointment by merit, but we have not yet succeeded 
 in introducing the merit system." Such an argument may be 
 turned against its supporters by the countercharge, which is 
 equally true, that we have not yet succeeded in introducing the 
 advanced form of public regulation which is the only salvation 
 and the last defense of the adherents of private management. In 
 point of fact, the whole discussion of municipal management pre- 
 supposes certain reasonable improvements both in the character 
 of public regulation and the character of the public service; for 
 unless we can regulate public utility companies far more satisfac- 
 torily than we have done in the past, we shall unquestionably and 
 inevitably come to municipal management. 
 
 (e) Finally, there is another fundamental characteristic of pub-
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 511 
 
 lie management which we shall regard as a virtue or defect accord- 
 ing to our political philosophy. Under private ownership, prices 
 are determined by considerations of profit; and persons who can- 
 not afford to pay the price of the service must go without it, 
 although they may be sadly in need of it. Under public manage- 
 ment, however, rates are determined by general social utility and 
 are frequently placed at less than the cost of services. Where 
 this happens, part of the expense of maintaining the industry falls 
 upon the general body of taxpayers, and it must be remembered 
 in this connection that probably a majority of the voters of the 
 present time pay no direct taxes. To persons of broad social sym- 
 pathies, confident of the honesty of democracy and anxious to 
 turn the powers of the State to ameliorating the lot of the poor and 
 unfortunate, this prospect of modifying charges by considerations 
 of social policy offers no terrors. To reduce street-car fares, for 
 instance, during the hours when our poorly paid workmen are 
 riding to their work, and in general to adjust prices so as to sub- 
 serve the highest social welfare, appears as an honorable oppor- 
 tunity, not as a dishonorable temptation. To persons of a harsher 
 social creed and a more pessimistic social philosophy, however, 
 the adjustment of rates to the greatest good of the greatest number 
 seems pernicious and dangerous. 
 
 Whether public management can fairly be expected to be as 
 efficient and progressive as private management is a question 
 which does not lend itself to brief discussion. At present, 
 however, we are unquestionably in an experimental stage; and 
 it is desirable not only that the commission plan shall be given 
 a thorough trial, but that public ownership and operation shall be 
 tested under such conditions as to enable an intelligent compari- 
 son to be made with the results of private management. States 
 having a commission empowered to enforce uniform accounting 
 will constitute great economic laboratories in this connection during 
 the next quarter of a century. In the end, however, it may be 
 that less emphasis will be placed upon cost of service and more 
 emphasis upon considerations of general social welfare than 
 is now done. Even if it shall transpire that private management 
 under a state commission is cheaper and more progressive than
 
 512 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 public management, the latter will still have a strong case in the 
 plea that it adapts the service to the greatest social welfare, abol- 
 ishes the struggle between the franchise corporations and the pub- 
 lic, dignifies municipal government, and, by enlarging the public 
 interests of the people, breeds in them a finer spirit of cooperation 
 and a deeper sense of social solidarity. At bottom this question 
 is not so much economic as social; and in the end that method 
 of management will prevail that best subserves the social well- 
 being, not that method of management which is cheapest. 
 
 Municipal Home Rule. The problem of municipal ownership, 
 as has been suggested, presents a contest between the highest form 
 of regulation which we can reasonably expect versus the best spe- 
 cies of municipal management which we are justified in anticipat- 
 ing. It is a conflict of potentialities. Whatever its outcome, there 
 is one important step which should be taken at once : cities should 
 be endowed with the power of introducing municipal manage- 
 ment, if they wish to try the experiment. In many cities to-day 
 private corporations have secured, often by bribery, perpetual 
 franchises in which rates and other conditions are authorized that 
 are manifestly unjust to the public. In such a situation the city 
 can do nothing but condemn, or threaten to condemn, the fran- 
 chise and property under its powers of eminent domain. Munici- 
 pal ownership, or the threat of municipal ownership, under which 
 the corporation might possibly acquiesce in reasonable regulation 
 offers the only remedy for this condition of affairs. 
 
 Worse than the above situation, however, is the utter helplessness 
 of those city governments which can neither undertake the opera- 
 tion of public utilities themselves, nor regulate the rates and serv- 
 ice of the private companies which control them; while the state 
 legislature, which has retained the power of regulation, does noth- 
 ing. This deadlock delivers over the city bound and captive into 
 the hands of the corporations. Even if the city decides to sell or 
 rent its new franchises, even if it prefers the conservative policy of 
 private management, it cannot dispose of its valuable rights to 
 the best advantage, unless it possesses the alternative of public 
 management with which to force the hand of the corporation. 
 It is sometimes thought that by offering franchises to the highest
 
 ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES OF MUNICIPALITIES 513 
 
 bidder, competition among private corporations will bring reason- 
 able and remunerative offers. This, however, is not the case. 
 The only bidder in most instances is the corporation already in 
 power, and where competitive bidding is required by law, "the 
 local governments have obtained no more favorable terms than 
 were prescribed as a minimum by state or local legislation. The 
 reason is obvious. The proposed franchise is almost invariably 
 petitioned for in the first instance by a duly organized corpora- 
 tion, which asks the right to occupy specifically named streets, 
 and which has carefully considered, in advance, construction plans 
 and probably financial results. Even when a considerable period 
 of time is allowed for others to investigate the proposed plan and 
 to estimate the value of the franchise, these possible competitors 
 are at a great disadvantage as compared with the original pro- 
 moters. It often happens that there are few people in a city who 
 are familiar with the street-railway business and at the same time 
 in command of the necessary capital. Effective competition is 
 still less likely when the proposed railway is in the nature of an 
 extension or outlying line, the success of which will depend almost 
 wholly upon cooperation with existing lines. The process of con- 
 solidation among street railways has gone so far in most large 
 cities that there is only one important system in existence with 
 which a new railway can be connected." l 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. What connection is there between governmental activity and popula- 
 tion ? Explain. 
 
 2. What is the essential characteristic of municipal government ? 
 
 3. Classify the functions commonly exercised by cities, and enumerate 
 the most significant characteristics which they possess in common. 
 
 4. What has been the most fertile source of political corruption in cities? 
 Would it disappear with adequate regulation ? 
 
 5. Why has general regulation been ineffective? 
 
 6. Under a system of adequate regulation, would it be desirable to en- 
 courage monopoly by chartering only one company with an indeterminate 
 franchise ? Why ? 
 
 7. Is it desirable that charters should contain specific provisions respect- 
 ing taxes, rates, and quality of service? Why? 
 
 1 Census Report, "Street and Electric Railways, 1902," p. 128. 
 2L
 
 514 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 8. Under a proper system of regulation, would the increase in franchise 
 values owing to growth of population and wealth (the unearned increment) 
 benefit the public or the private company ? 
 
 9. Would municipal plants pay taxes under existing tax laws? Should 
 they pay such taxes? 
 
 10. Assuming that the poorer classes pay a larger share of their income 
 for street-railway transportation than the wealthier classes, would it be de- 
 sirable for private companies to earn large profits, even if such profits were 
 turned over in whole or part to the city government ? 
 
 n. Under the same hypothesis, would it be legitimate for a municipal 
 street railway to charge passengers less than cost, meeting the deficit by tax 
 levies ? 
 
 12. What advantages are possible from municipal management that can- 
 not be secured from private operation under good regulation ? 
 
 13. Why should municipalities be granted the option of acquiring and 
 managing the public utilities? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BEMIS, E. W., and others. Municipal Monopolies. 
 
 DARWIN, L. Municipal Trade, passim. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Evolution of Industrial Society, Part II, Chap. V, "Municipal 
 
 Ownership of Natural Monopolies," pp. 225-254. 
 FOOTE, A. R. Municipal Public Service Industries. 
 HOWE, F. C. The City the Hope of Democracy, passim. "Municipal 
 
 Ownership in Great Britain," Bulletin of the [U.S.] Bureau of Labor 
 
 No. 62, January, 1906. 
 JOHNSON, E. R. "Public Regulation of Street Railway Transportation," 
 
 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 
 
 March, 1907, pp. 31-47. 
 
 Municipal A/airs, Vol. IV, No. i, 1900; and Vol. VI, No. 4, 1002-1903. 
 POND, O. L. "Municipal Control of Public Utilities," Columbia Studies 
 
 in History, Economics, and Public Law, Vol. XXV. 
 Proceedings of the Annual Meetings of the National Municipal League. 
 Report of the London Commission on London Traffic, 1905. 
 Report of the Special Committee of the State of Massachusetts, 1898 : " The 
 
 Relations between Cities and Towns and Street Railway Companies." 
 Special Census Report, Street and Electric Railways, 1002. 
 Special Census Report, Telephones and Telegraphs, 1002. 
 Special Census Report, Central Electric Light and Power Stations, 1902. 
 United States Supreme Court Reports, Vol. 143, p. 339. San Diego Land 
 
 Co. vs. National City, etc.
 
 CHAPTER XXX 
 SOCIALISM 
 
 Socialism Defined. Socialists seek the establishment of in- 
 dustrial democracy through the instrumentality of the State. 
 Our political organization is to become also an economic industrial 
 organization. Socialism contemplates an expansion of the busi- 
 ness functions of government until the more important businesses 
 are absorbed. Private property in profit-producing capital and 
 rent-producing land is to be abolished. Socialists make no war 
 upon capital; what they object to is the private capitalist. They 
 desire to socialize capital and to abolish capitalists as a distinct 
 class. Their ideal, then, is not, as is supposed by the uninformed, 
 an equal division of existing wealth, but a change in the funda- 
 mental conditions governing the acquisition of incomes. 
 
 Socialists usually say that labor creates all wealth. No rational 
 socialist means thereby to deny that land and capital are factors 
 of production, but as these are passive factors, they hold that their 
 owners ought not to receive a share of the product unless they 
 personally are useful members of the community. Labor is. the 
 active factor, and all production is carried on for the sake of man. 
 Land and capital are simply the tools of man. Socialists admit 
 that the owners of these tools must receive a return for them when 
 industry is organized as it is now; hence they desire that these 
 tools should become public property. They wish to make of uni- 
 versal application the command of the Apostle Paul, " If a man 
 will not work, neither let him eat." 
 
 Distributive Justice. Socialists, in common with a great many 
 other people who do not accept their attitude toward the organiza- 
 tion of industry, desire distributive justice. As to what constitutes 
 justice they are not wholly agreed, but there is among them a 
 tendency to accept equality or needs as a basis rather than produc- 
 
 5*5
 
 516 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tivity. Some, it is true, have advocated an almost mechanical 
 equality, but most socialists to-day would regard the question of 
 a precise standard for the distribution of income as not of present 
 importance. They are simply agreed in this, that the distribution 
 of the present day is wholly unjust. They think that men to-day 
 do not have equal chances in life, that there is too much privilege. 
 The big rewards, they think, to-day go to those who are shrewd 
 and cunning, who are skillful in manipulating stocks and bonds, 
 or who are favored by inheritance with a good start, rather than 
 to those who render great social service. The inventors, poets, 
 authors, scientists, skilled mechanics, and factory managers, they 
 allege, are the large producers, but they do not get the big prizes. 
 
 Varieties of Socialism. The foregoing characterization ap- 
 plies to most persons who have been called socialists, but the genus 
 contains a number of species which should be distinguished. 
 
 (i) One group has been called " Utopian." There are those 
 who might object to this term on the ground that all of them are 
 Utopian. Nevertheless, some are more so than others. This first 
 group contains those who have become impressed with the evils 
 of the present competitive system and propose the collective owner- 
 ship of the means of production as a remedy, in much the same 
 spirit with which a physician writes a prescription to cure his 
 patient. There have been many attempts to picture to us how 
 smoothly things would proceed if men could only be persuaded 
 to try the collective ownership of land and capital. As a type of 
 this class we may take Robert Owen. His life was contemporane- 
 ous with the Industrial Revolution in England, he himself being a 
 successful manufacturer. He saw with his own eyes the evils 
 of unrestricted competition, and was filled with an earnest desire 
 to better the condition of the working classes. He is remembered 
 as a factory reformer and promoter of voluntary cooperation, but 
 yet he regarded these efforts as not sufficiently radical. He thought 
 human nature must be reformed by careful training from child- 
 hood in an atmosphere of association, instead of the self-seeking, 
 commercial atmosphere which surrounded him. He spent his 
 large fortune in an attempt to carry out his ideas regarding the 
 reconstruction of society. Among his projects was the founding
 
 SOCIALISM 517 
 
 of a colony at New Harmony, Indiana, where no private property 
 or competition should exist. After a continuance of two years, 
 the experiment ended, as most other similar enterprises have, a 
 complete failure. In this group would also be placed Saint- 
 Simon, Fourier, Cabet, Blanc, 1 and Bellamy. 
 
 (2) The " Marxian " socialists call themselves " scientific," 
 as distinguished from the idealistic writers just mentioned. They 
 insist that they have no cure-all for the ills of society. Socialism 
 in their eyes is, in the main, only an explanation of what is happen- 
 ing. The private capitalistic system is breaking down, they say, 
 and the logical result must be the collective ownership of the 
 means of production as the next stage in social evolution. They 
 say that setting aside all question of " ought " or " desirability," 
 collective ownership is coming, and we might as well adjust our- 
 selves to it. The four leading features of the Marxian philoso- 
 phy are: (a) the study of society as an evolutionary product ; 
 (b) the economic interpretation of history, according to which 
 our whole social life, including our ideas concerning religion, art, 
 marriage, etc., are but a reflex of past and present economic 
 conditions; (c) the doctrine of surplus value, according to which 
 the income of the capitalist class does not represent a return for 
 abstinence, but results from the fact that through their ownership 
 of the means of production they can compel the laboring class to 
 work for them a longer number of hours than is necessary to pro- 
 duce the wages which the laborers receive. What is produced in 
 this additional number of hours is the source of capitalist income; 
 and (d) the doctrine of the class struggle, which finds a deep antag- 
 onism between the capitalist class and the laboring class, that 
 can only result in the overthrow of the capitalist class and the tri- 
 umph of the laboring class. Most socialists now believe that this 
 victory will be won without bloodshed, as a result of a gradual 
 increase in the strength of the socialist party as a political organiza- 
 tion. 
 
 (3) The Fabian Socialists, of whom the members of the 
 Fabian Society of England are types, have disapproved both of the 
 
 1 Louis Blanc was less " Utopian " than the others. He was transitional and 
 in reality paved the way for the German and later "scientific" movement.
 
 518 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 founding of Utopian settlements and of the philosophy of Marx. 
 The aim of this society has been to spread socialistic ideas by 
 the dissemination of knowledge on the subject, rather than by an 
 organized political movement, advocating this or that reform as 
 opportunity indicated. The membership has come largely from 
 the educated middle class, and has never been very large, although 
 the society has exercised considerable influence. Practically, 
 some of the conservative members of the Marxian school, such 
 as Bernstein, in Germany, and Jaur^s, in France, do not differ 
 greatly from the Fabians. 
 
 The following words of Jaures on the method of realizing the 
 socialist ideal are of interest in this connection : 
 
 "All Socialists, indeed, some openly, others with infinite precautions, some 
 with a mischievous Viennese good-nature, declare it to be untrue that, taken 
 as a whole, the economic material condition of the proletariat is getting worse 
 and worse. It must be conceded, after taking account of the tendency to 
 sink and the tendency to rise, that in the immediate reality of life, the tendency 
 to sink is not the stronger. Once this has been granted, it is no longer pos- 
 sible to repeat after Marx and Engels that the capitalist system will perish 
 because it does not insure to those whom it exploits the minimum necessities 
 of life. It follows from the same admission that it has also become puerile 
 to expect that an economic cataclysm, menacing the proletariat in its very 
 existence, will bring about, by the revolt of the instinct of self-perservation, 
 the ' violent overthrow of the bourgeoisie.' 
 
 "It is not by an unexpected counter-stroke of political agitation that the 
 proletariat will gain supreme power, but by the methodical and legal organi- 
 zation of its own forces under the law of the democracy and universal suffrage. 
 It is not by the collapse of the capitalistic bourgeoisie, but by the growth of 
 the proletariat, that the Communist order will gradually install itself in our 
 society." l 
 
 (4) The Christian socialists. About the middle of the nine- 
 teenth century, such men as Kingsley, Maurice, and Hughes in 
 England were much impressed by the misery of the poor, arid they 
 attacked the competitive system as being responsible for the evils 
 which they saw. Voluntary cooperation and the elevation of the 
 workingman's character seemed to them the proper remedies. 
 Thus their theories hardly fall under the head of socialism as we 
 have defined the term. In Germany and France, also, social 
 
 1 Studies in Socialism (trans, by M. Minturn), pp. 167-169.
 
 SOCIALISM 519 
 
 movements have been organized by adherents of both Protestant 
 and Catholic Churches. In the United States all shades of opinion 
 have been included under Christian socialism, but the term should 
 apply only to those who advocate the collective ownership of the 
 means of production on the ground primarily that this is required 
 by the teaching of the Christian religion. 
 
 (5) State socialism is a term frequently used in German dis- 
 cussion to designate those who favor an extension of the economic 
 functions of government without any great change in existing 
 class relations. 
 
 (6) " Socialists of the chair " (Kathedersozialismus) refers to 
 the university professors who have advocated State interference 
 with property rights to any extent demanded by public welfare, 
 and have opposed the extreme laissez-faire doctrines of the older 
 economists. These men are not to be classed as socialists, the 
 term being used as a reproach by their conservative opponents, 
 and the designation has now chiefly historical significance. 
 
 Communism. Communism was the term employed by Karl 
 Marx to distinguish his own philosophy from the " Utopian" 
 schemes of such men as Owen, which he termed socialistic. But 
 to-day the reverse has become the common usage. Communism 
 now very generally signifies the abolition of private property not 
 only in production goods, but also in consumption goods, whereas 
 socialists contemplate the retention of private property in income. 
 In this case there would be provision of private property for every 
 one, and in this respect socialists emphasize and extend the idea 
 of private property. 
 
 Socialism an Extension of Existing Institutions. Our govern- 
 ment owns the post office; most governments the telegraph. 
 Nearly all own the wagon roads. Some own the canals and rail- 
 ways. Many governments own factories. Probably every na- 
 tional government does at least a little manufacturing. Most 
 governments cultivate forests, and some cultivate arable land. 
 We have only to imagine an extension of what already exists until 
 government enterprise dominates in manufactures, mining, trans- 
 portation, commerce, and carries on, in short, most productive 
 enterprises, and we have socialism pure and simple.
 
 520 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 But saying that socialism is an extension of existing institutions 
 may lead to a misconception. The elimination of private capital- 
 ism is supposed to work a most radical change in many branches 
 of our social life. The commercial spirit would be abolished, and 
 with it all that is dependent upon it. We are trained, it is alleged, 
 to-day from childhood up to try to "make money," and this ac- 
 centuates the selfish elements in our nature; and it is therefore 
 maintained that our present system does nothing to promote, and 
 does much to hinder, the development of the brotherly spirit. 
 
 The Strength of Socialism. Socialism makes perhaps its 
 strongest claim in its plea, first, for a scientific organization of the 
 productive forces of society, and second, for a just distribution of 
 the annual social income. It is said that the present production 
 of economic goods is small in proportion to population, but the 
 socialist replies, "Naturally enough. Competition is wasteful. 
 Two railways are built where one would suffice. Two trains run 
 parallel between two cities where one would serve the public equally 
 well. Three times as many milk wagons, horses, and drivers are 
 required to serve the people with milk as would suffice if the milk 
 business were organized like the mail distribution in cities. Look 
 at the shops, wholesale and retail, and see the waste of human 
 force. Without competition, the whole dry goods and grocery 
 business could be carried on with a third of the present economic 
 expenditure of force. Reflect on all the idle classes in modern 
 society. Socialism would set everybody to work, and, making 
 each one dependent on his own exertions for success, would stimu- 
 late all energies." The argument is a telling one, but it does not 
 prove its point unless we grant that the present waste and idle- 
 ness cannot be suppressed or greatly diminished without a depar- 
 ture from the fundamental principles of our present industrial 
 order, or that the waste and idleness are not counterbalanced by 
 advantages. 
 
 Justice is a strong plea in the socialist philosophy. It cannot 
 be for one moment claimed that each one's income is at present 
 in proportion to his services to humanity. Income in proportion 
 to industrial merit is attractive to an ethical sentiment. But can- 
 not we approximate justice in distribution on the basis of the exist-
 
 SOCIALISM 521 
 
 ing order? There is nothing distinctively socialistic about the 
 desire for distributive justice. It is a feeling that actuates those 
 who work for the control of monopolies and corporations, for tax 
 reform, regulation of inheritances, etc. The socialist simply differs 
 from these people in his method of attaining his ideal. 
 
 The socialist criticism of the present regime is especially severe 
 in the matter of unemployment. There are always some men 
 who are able and willing to work, who are out of jobs, and periodic- 
 ally, with the coming of crises and depressions, the lack of em- 
 ployment becomes widespread. There is, of course, no lack of 
 need for additional goods; the difficulty is entirely a matter of 
 business organization. Again, it is urged that to-day goods are 
 made for sale, not for use, as they would be under the socialistic 
 regime. Adulteration, deception, and "cheap and nasty" goods 
 are the direct outcome of a system of private capitalism. In the 
 socialistic state we are told the business of the shopkeeper is to 
 help you find what you really need; at the present time it is to 
 his interest to persuade you to buy what you do not need or what 
 will give him the greatest profit. The spirit of competition is to 
 the socialist simply warfare. In every business establishment a 
 good deal of the most highly paid labor is devoted, not to the pro- 
 duction of goods, but to finding a market. Ability to fight one's 
 competitor is quite as essential in business as is the ability to turn 
 out good products. 
 
 The Weakness of Socialism. (i) Strong as may be the fore- 
 going indictment of the existing industrial system, it is not sufficient 
 to indicate that socialism is to be the necessary or the desirable 
 outcome. The modern machine age is little more than a century 
 old, and some of its most important phases are very recent. The 
 dire predictions made by Karl Marx and his followers on the 
 strength of some of the earliest phenomena of the factory system 
 have not been borne out, and similarly the evils of to-day may 
 possibly be very largely eliminated without departing from our 
 fundamental institutions. In short, the first weak point in the 
 socialist's position is that he attempts to predict the course of 
 economic evolution too far in advance. That we shall have a 
 juster distribution of wealth in the future, and that we shall elimi-
 
 522 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 nate many of the present wastes of production seems probable, 
 but whether this will be accomplished by a socialistic organization 
 or not, it would be hazardous to predict. It is desirable to have 
 ideals to work toward, but we should not pin our faith now to a 
 future method for attaining them, for no one can say that the 
 collective ownership of all of the important means of production 
 presents a question that needs to be decided now. 
 
 (2) The socialist underestimates the efficiency of the present 
 system. To-day there is a premium on energy and thrift. Much 
 may be wasted, but much is also produced. That socialism would 
 result in a larger sum total of goods for consumption has never 
 been proved. But on the other hand, we can say that the present 
 regime is continually offering more and more to the mass of 
 the people. Their standard of life is continually rising. Our 
 economic world is a bettering world. 
 
 (3) The socialist is also in other respects too pessimistic with 
 respect to the present. He sees all of the starvation, misery, 
 luxury, and extravagance, but he passes by the millions of happy 
 homes scattered throughout the land. He does not see that the 
 world is full of opportunity for the rising generation, that even if 
 the chance for the ownership of an independent business for the 
 ordinary man is smaller, the things which he can enjoy, if he is of 
 average intelligence and energy, are much greater than ever before 
 in the world's history. 
 
 (4) The socialist underestimates the importance of individual 
 responsibility. To-day a man is confronted by the stern necessity 
 of making his own way, and this must have some good effect upon 
 character. On the whole, the lazy and incompetent are sifted out. 
 Bad heredity and a lack of proper training are the cause of a good 
 deal of economic misfortune. It is well to distinguish the criticism 
 here made from the common error of supposing that socialism 
 would necessarily crush individuality, that we must all dress 
 and eat alike, etc. 
 
 (5) The socialist underestimates the importance of free enter- 
 prise in industry. If a man now believes that he can develop a 
 certain industry that will satisfy important wants of the people 
 in the future, he does not need to secure the consent of some gov-
 
 SOCIALISM 523 
 
 ernment official to make the experiment. The possibilities of a 
 free and spontaneous development should be safeguarded from 
 governmental routine to every possible extent. 
 
 (6) Perhaps the most frequently mentioned objection to social- 
 ism is the danger to liberty. Under socialism there would be 
 simply the public sphere of employment, and there is reason to 
 fear that the inability to escape from the public sphere would com- 
 pel the submission to onerous and tyrannical conditions imposed 
 by the administrative heads of the business in which one might be 
 engaged. The socialists, it is true, have a rejoinder in the fact 
 that this objection refers to liberty in the negative sense rather than 
 in the positive sense of the power to enjoy goods, and yet there 
 are many persons who fear the tyranny of the majority. Those 
 in whose hands centered political and economic control would have 
 tremendous power, however they might be selected or appointed. 
 As in the religious sphere in the past, so in the economic sphere 
 in the future, we may find that compulsory cooperation is incom- 
 patible with human nature. 
 
 (7) The Marxian socialists may be criticised for the importance 
 which they attach to the economic interpretation of history, for 
 the validity of that proposition does not establish the validity of 
 the socialist contention. If it be true that our social life is a reflex 
 of our economic activity, it still does not necessarily follow that 
 our economic development is going to be such as will land us in 
 socialism. Their doctrine of the class struggle also does not give 
 an accurate account of existing conditions. We have a laboring 
 class and a capitalist class, it is true, but there is also a considerable 
 class, perhaps large enough to hold the balance of power between 
 the other two, which does not sympathize exclusively with either 
 labor or capital. 
 
 Social Reform. There are those who recognize the strength of 
 the socialist's criticism of the existing economic and social order, 
 but who believe it wise to attack the various problems confronting 
 us one at a time. Social reform seems likely to accomplish more 
 valuable results than socialism. We have a monopoly problem 
 before us now. Its solution may involve a considerable extension 
 of government enterprise. Why not concentrate our efforts upon
 
 5 2 4 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 that problem instead of making up our minds now whether some 
 day the greater proportion of the industrial field must be collect- 
 ively owned and managed ? 
 
 The Socialist Movement. In every country of importance at 
 the present time there is an organized socialist movement, and 
 while it may never attain its ideals, it is exercising an important 
 influence on present-day affairs. This is most marked in the case 
 of Germany. Its voting strength has been steadily increasing, 
 although in the last election its representation in the Reichstag 
 was considerably reduced, as shown in the following table: 
 
 
 VOTES 
 
 REPRESENTATIVES 
 
 1878 
 
 437. I0 
 
 9 
 
 1881 
 
 312,000 
 
 12 
 
 1884 
 
 550,000 
 
 24 
 
 1887 
 
 763,100 
 
 II 
 
 1890 
 
 1,427,300 
 
 35 
 
 i893 
 
 1,786,700 
 
 44 
 
 1898 
 
 2,107,100 
 
 56 
 
 J 93 
 
 3,010,800 
 
 77 l 
 
 1907 
 
 3,251,000 
 
 43 
 
 1 The membership later rose to 81. The total number of seats in the Reichstag is 397. 
 
 Although the official platform of the party adheres strictly to 
 the orthodox Marxian faith, the party itself has worked for many 
 reforms tending to favor the lower classes, and a large element of 
 the party (the " revisionist " wing) is in favor of putting the doc- 
 trine of the class struggle and complete collectivism in the back- 
 ground, and laying main emphasis for the present upon social 
 reform. In France there are a number of socialist factions, or 
 various degrees of radicalism, nominally united in one party, the 
 factional strife being one of the prominent characteristics of the 
 movement in that country. Their combined representation in the 
 chamber of deputies is about one seventh of the total membership. 
 A member of the moderate group, Millerand, was made Minister of 
 Commerce (1899) in the Waldeck -Rousseau cabinet. In a num- 
 ber of French municipalities the government is almost completely
 
 SOCIALISM 525 
 
 socialistic in personnel. The result in these cases has been an 
 increased public activity in behalf of workingmen, the poor, and 
 the unfortunate. 
 
 In Belgium the success of the socialist party in promoting the 
 cooperative movement has been striking. In England the or- 
 ganized socialistic party had small influence in political affairs 
 until recently, when a " labor group " was organized in Parlia- 
 ment. The Collectivist activity of the London County Council 
 may also be mentioned in this connection. In the United States 
 there afe two rival parties, the Socialist party of America and 
 the Socialist Labor party (of declining importance) both having 
 platforms based upon the Marxian philosophy. A number of 
 mayors and state legislators have been elected, but there are no 
 socialist representatives in Congress. In 1904 the Presidential 
 Socialist vote was about 3 per cent of the total votes cast. 
 
 Socialists have rendered good service by calling attention to 
 social problems, by forcing us to reflect on the condition of the less 
 fortunate classes, by quickening our consciences; also by helping 
 us to form the habit, acquired by few as yet, of looking at all ques- 
 tions from the standpoint of the public welfare and not merely 
 of individual gain; finally, by calling our attention to the nature 
 of the industrial functions of government and helping us to sepa- 
 rate rationally the private industrial sphere from the public indus- 
 trial sphere. A number of questions having no connection with 
 socialism have been, even by socialists, not infrequently associated 
 with it. Atheism and free love may be mentioned. Socialists 
 generally, however, regard religion and marriage as changing 
 institutions. 
 
 Anarchism. In contrast with the socialist, the anarchist holds 
 that the ideal social arrangement is that men should freely and 
 spontaneously form cooperative groups. The anarchists attack 
 government and deny the right of one man to exercise authority 
 over another. Freedom, independence, self-reliance, non-com- 
 pulsion is what appeals to them. Such an ideal contains nothing 
 reprehensible, but its complete attainment is impossible. Some 
 governmental compulsion seems necessary with human nature 
 as it is or is ever likely to be. The anarchist is not opposed to
 
 526 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the principle of association; he simply asks that the association 
 be voluntary. The anarchist ideal is thus portrayed by Kropot- 
 kin: 
 
 "This society will be composed of a multitude of associations federated 
 for all the purposes which require federation; trade federations for produc- 
 tions of all sorts, agricultural, industrial, intellectual, artistic; communes 
 for consumption, making provision for dwellings, gas-works, supplies of food, 
 sanitary arrangements, etc.; federations of communes, among themselves, 
 and federations of communes with trade organizations; and finally, wider 
 groups covering all the country, or several countries, composed of men who 
 collaborate for the satisfaction of such economic, intellectual, artistic, and 
 moral needs as are not limited to a given territory. All these will combine 
 directly by means of free agreements between them, just as the railway 
 companies or the postal departments of different countries cooperate now, 
 without having a central railway or postal government, even though the 
 former are actuated by merely egotistic aims, and the latter belong to different 
 and often hostile states; or as meteorologists, the Alpine clubs, the lifeboat 
 stations in Great Britain, the cyclists, the teachers, and so on, combine for 
 all sorts of work in common, for intellectual pursuits or simply for pleasure." 1 
 
 Many persons class anarchists and socialists together as simply 
 dangerous persons. One thing they do have in common, and that 
 is, discontent with existing conditions. Othenvise their views 
 are radically divergent. 
 
 Anarchists differ among themselves. The leading " Commun- 
 ist-Anarchist " is Kropotkin, who advocates revolutionary tactics. 
 Bakunine and Stirner have also stood for violence. The " in- 
 dividualistic anarchists," such as Tolstoi and Tucker, pursue a 
 peaceful policy of non-resistance. Godwin and Proudhon may 
 be called anarchistic reformers. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Is the public purchase of a street-railway system socialistic ? 
 
 2. Does William Morris, in his News from Nowhere, picture socialism or 
 anarchism ? 
 
 3. Compare the Amana Society with the New Harmony Community. 
 
 4. What is meant by the economic interpretation of history? Is it ac- 
 cepted by thinkers who are not socialists ? 
 
 5. What thoughts are common to the various platforms given in the ap- 
 pendices to Ely's Socialism and Social Reform ? 
 
 6. Write a sketch of the life of Josiah Warren. 
 
 1 Memoirs of a Revolutionist, pp- 39 8 ~399-
 
 SOCIALISM 527 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BAX, E. B. Essays in Socialism, New and Old. (From a socialist point of 
 
 view.) 
 BROOKS, J. G. The Social Unrest, Chaps. VII-X. (Sympathetic critic 
 
 of socialism.) 
 COMMONS, J. R. "The Class Conflict," American Journal of Archaeology, 
 
 May, 1906. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Socialism and Social Reform, and French and German Social- 
 ism, and the articles on Socialism and Socialist Parties in the new 
 
 International Encyclopaedia. 
 
 ELTZBACHER, PAUL. Anarchism. (Trans, by S. T. Byington.) 
 ENSOR, R. C. K. (Editor). Modern Socialism, ad ed. (A collection of essays 
 
 by leading socialists.) 
 HILLQUTT, MORRIS. History of Socialism in the United States. (By a 
 
 socialist.) 
 
 HINDS, W. A. American Communities. (Descriptive.) 
 JAURES, JEAN. Studies in Socialism. (Trans, by M. Minturn.) (By a 
 
 conservative French socialist.) 
 KlRKUP, T. History of Socialism. 
 
 LE ROSSIGNOL. Orthodox Socialism. (Criticism of leading doctrines.) 
 MALLOCK, W. H. Aristocracy and Evolution. (Opposed to socialism.) 
 MORRIS, WILLIAM. News from Nowhere. 
 
 RAE, J. Contemporary Socialism, ad ed. (Opposed to socialism.) 
 SPENCER, HERBERT. Man versus the State. (Opposed to socialism.) 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. The Economic Interpretation of History. 
 TUCKER, BENJAMIN. Instead of a Book, ad ed. (By a leading anarchist.) 
 VEBLEN, T. B. The Theory of Business Enterprise, Chap. IX. (Severely 
 
 critical of existing conditions, but not accepting socialism.) 
 WELLS, H. G. A Modern Utopia. 
 ZENKER, E. V. Anarchism. (Attempts to give an exposition of anarchism 
 
 without taking sides.)
 
 CHAPTER XXXI 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 
 
 THE socialistic ideal of a highly centralized and delicately co- 
 ordinated industrial system, discussed in the preceding chapter, 
 is confronted with a sharp contrast in the agricultural industry 
 as it exists to-day. Even in the most advanced countries, agri- 
 culture is still strikingly decentralized, and furnishes at once the 
 best illustration and the most fertile source of economic individu- 
 alism. 
 
 Size of Farms. Agriculture has never been, and shows no 
 disposition to become, a large-scale industry in the United States. 
 The statistical evidence upon which this assertion rests is pre- 
 sented in compressed form in Table I upon the following page. 
 A comparison of columns 2 and 3 brings out the interesting fact 
 that, in every decade except one since 1850, the number of farms 
 has increased more rapidly than the general population. In 1850 
 there was one farm for every 16 persons; but one for every 13.3 
 persons in 1900; 1 one farm for every 14 rural residents (persons 
 outside of cities containing 8000 inhabitants or more) in 1850, but 
 one for every 9 rural residents in 1900. Moreover, there was 
 in 1900 one farm of 50 acres or more for every 13.4 rural residents, 
 thus indicating that the proportionate increase in the number of 
 farms is due " not to the addition of mere potato patches or small 
 tracts of land used incidentally for agricultural purposes, but to a 
 marked increase in the number of real farms. This growth marks 
 an increase among tne rural population in the number of farmers 
 whose head members are their own masters, and is a movement 
 toward economic individualism as distinct as the opposite tend- 
 
 1 The increasing proportion of adult males in the general population somewhat 
 reduces the significance of this statement. 
 
 528
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 
 
 529 
 
 HH 
 
 W < 
 t-1 W 
 
 pq 
 
 f 8 
 
 o a 
 u S 
 
 v 52 u v 
 
 E 8i{ 
 
 250 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 *?*!*? 
 
 pi ci M 
 
 gi 
 
 ^ 
 
 < W 
 
 3 S 
 
 |8| 
 
 m 
 
 M 
 
 vr> Tl- to 
 
 <** ** **) ; ; ; 
 
 M M M 
 
 * u 
 
 b< 
 
 2 b 
 s 8|| 
 
 & s g 
 < * 
 
 n 
 
 M 
 
 O in ro 
 
 M t^ PO 
 
 O w 
 
 3 ~ 
 
 51 
 
 M 
 M 
 
 O f*5 O OO O r^ 
 >0 TJ- ro *) rO *} 
 
 * x * 
 
 O ft. H 
 
 
 
 
 is 
 
 O 3 
 
 < CL, 
 
 U ?" _ 
 
 i | 1 s 
 
 5 til 
 
 O 
 
 M 
 
 *> 1 ^9 " *J 
 
 (4 > O *9 *O 40 
 
 "B 3 
 
 "2 "^ a 
 
 
 ro >O t^ N ro "1 
 
 H fc, 
 
 Jsjj 
 
 
 
 M M tf) eo <r> 
 
 00 00 00 00 00 00 
 
 H 
 
 m 
 
 < 
 
 ^ i s 
 
 ^ c c 
 
 CO 
 
 CO OO M M O 10 
 
 ro O O O M O 
 
 s 
 
 111! 
 
 
 
 
 6) 
 P 
 
 < 
 
 elh 
 
 S _, fc u 
 
 h ll fl 
 
 r 
 
 >O O> * O M CO 
 O O ^ ^ to 10 
 O O >0 t^ N 
 cT cT N N" ro cf 
 
 O 
 
 < 
 
 1 
 
 < 
 
 gs 
 
 cS g^ 
 
 it 
 
 IO 
 
 rj- ro oo fo * oo 
 
 t>. N ro >O O *5 
 o m O ro ^ f- 
 PO tO ro <*5 O fT 
 
 
 
 h. ./ 
 
 . "S 
 
 
 *> to O O 00 O 
 
 HOD 
 
 J S 
 
 m 
 
 M OO M M O* OO 
 
 3 M M 8 
 
 S. 
 
 
 
 Me- 2 
 *|S 
 
 3 
 
 E2 
 
 * 
 
 \O O PO M >O 
 vd <3 ro to <> 
 
 TJ- PO PO >o o\ o 
 
 H M M M H C1 
 
 K S3 : 
 H < c 
 
 I S g 
 
 
 l- O\ M *O vO 
 
 * g 
 .2' 
 
 !|| 
 
 L1S 
 
 n 
 
 S'f 6 w >o : 
 ro N fO 
 
 s g 
 
 H < 
 
 n 
 
 < a 
 
 
 r^ O\ t^ M w 
 
 a. u 
 
 Sa 
 
 fe Q 
 
 fc< M 
 O H 
 
 K 
 
 
 
 >o PO o o M 
 
 w to PO * 
 
 Hi 
 
 Id 
 
 ll 
 
 
 
 in 
 
 ! l 
 
 M 
 
 M 
 
 r^. M t>- 10 r^- PO 
 o rf o oo r~ t^ 
 
 \O_ O n ON ON O, O, 
 
 o^ ^f oo o^ ^* o\ 
 
 PO vO O 10 *T * 
 
 t^. 10 q^ vq^ q * 
 10 'f ^? cT ci i-T 
 
 en 
 
 B 
 
 > 
 
 'a 
 
 a"" 
 
 Q O O O 
 
 O ON CO *>. vO 10 
 O\ 00 00 OO OO OO 
 
 U 
 
 
 w 

 
 530 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ency in cities toward wage service and dependence upon em- 
 ployers." 1 
 
 Coming back to Table I, we find additional evidence in support 
 of the generalization just quoted. Columns 4 and 5 make it plain 
 that the bonanza farm which once occupied such a prominent 
 place in foreign and socialistic discussions of American agriculture, 
 is an exception which promises to become rarer and not more 
 frequent with the passage of time. Columns 6, 7, and 8 show 
 that the increase in the value of the average farm is trivial far 
 less than the increase in the wealth of the average member of 
 the agricultural class. Columns q, 10, and n furnish surprising 
 evidence to the effect that the land itself is not absorbing a larger 
 and larger share of the farmer's capital as time passes. Prac- 
 tically the only noticeable change is the increasing importance of 
 live stock on the farm a change which is regarded by practically 
 every authority as wholesome and encouraging. Finally, columns 
 12, 13, and 14 reflect in statistical form the growing scarcity of 
 farm labor and the increasing use of farm machinery in the culti- 
 vation of the staple crops. 
 
 The foregoing statistics are only approximately correct, and 
 conceal a great variety of conflicting movements in different parts 
 of the country. But they represent the true average condition, 
 the real resultant movement; and study of the details furnishes 
 no reason to question the general accuracy of their showing. 
 American agriculture shows no tendency to become either a large 
 scale or a highly capitalized form of industry. 
 
 Even Mr. Prothero, as the following quotation shows, has been led into 
 error on this point. "Statistics show that, in a country [the United States] 
 where estates in fee tail are obsolete or abolished by law, where there is no 
 feudal tenure, no primogeniture, no privileged class, in a country, finally, 
 where the transfer of land is simple, easy, and cheap, large estates and large 
 farms have become the rule. The United States contain more tenant farmers 
 than any other country in the world, and, where this class exists, those who 
 do the drudgery do not own the land. Land monopoly is becoming the 
 system of America." * 
 
 1 Twelfth Census, " Agriculture," Part I, p. xxxiv. 
 
 'Prothero, R. E. The Pioneers and Progress of English Farming (1888), 
 p. 146.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 531 
 
 So much for the size of the farm as it is; the next question con- 
 cerns the size of the farm as it should be. Would the prosperity 
 of the agricultural classes and the general welfare be increased 
 by expanding or reducing the farm unit, by more or less intensive 
 farming? 
 
 Obviously no simple answer can be given to this question. 
 The value of the land or the rent it will bring is perhaps the most 
 important factor: high rental value indicates that the margin of 
 cultivation has been forced to a comparatively low point, and makes 
 it both necessary and profitable to work the land intensively, for 
 the same reason that the owner of a very valuable manufacturing 
 plant is inclined to run it night and day, if possible, in order to 
 reduce that part of the cost of production which represents fixed 
 charges or interest on the capital that is sunk in the enterprise. 
 In addition to the factor of rent, the amount of capital that he can 
 command, the kind of farming in which he is most skilled, the 
 character of the labor he can secure, the proximity of markets, and 
 the adequacy of transportation facilities, all must be taken into 
 account by the individual farmer in determining how large a farm 
 he will attempt to manage and how intensively he will farm it. 
 
 Speaking generally, however, two powerful but counteracting 
 forces can be detected in the agricultural industry, which prevent 
 the industry from becoming either predominantly intensive or 
 predominantly extensive. On the one hand, machinery can be 
 employed most advantageously on a comparatively large farm, 
 and, other things being equal, the use of labor-saving machinery is 
 desirable. On the other hand, the importance of labor is greater, 
 and the importance of the manager or entrepreneur is less, in agri- 
 culture than in manufactures; and on this account the stimulus 
 given to the individual laborer by the sense of proprietorship is 
 a far more potent factor in agriculture than in other industries. 
 Large factories controlled by one entrepreneur employing hundreds 
 of dependent workmen have proved economically superior in the 
 manufacturing industry, because of the possibility of supervising 
 the labor, checking and measuring its efficiency automatically. 
 In agriculture, however, technical skill remains far more important 
 relatively to those commercial or financial talents which distin-
 
 532 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 guish the successful employer than in any other great division 
 of production. 
 
 This question is primarily one of private profit, which the indi- 
 vidual must decide for himself, but the legislator and the scientific 
 student can be of some assistance in helping to develop that most 
 difficult branch of commercial science farm accounting and 
 in keeping the farmer alive to those changes in prices, wages, and 
 transportation charges to which the farm organization must adjust 
 itself. On the whole, however, the emphasis is wisely placed by 
 the average educator, at the present time, upon the possibilities 
 and opportunities of more intensive farming. In the past, exten- 
 sive farming has been, and justifiably so, the rule in this country, 
 and the force of inertia is all directed that way. But the demands 
 of the future will be in the opposite direction. As cities multiply 
 and the market approaches the farm, intensive farming will be 
 forced upon the people, and the readier we are to adapt ourselves 
 to this change, the less will be the friction and loss. Moreover, 
 the ability to earn a living by intensive farming makes it easier 
 to acquire a farm; and we are strongly of the opinion, as will ap- 
 pear hereafter, that widely diffused ownership is better than a 
 general system of tenancy, even where land values are high. 
 
 Finally, it may be noted that practically every European country 
 attempts by legislation to increase the number of small holdings; 
 and in a mixed problem of this kind, which is as much psycholog- 
 ical and social as strictly economic, the instincts of the majority 
 are likely to have a sound social basis. Even in England, where 
 comparatively large farming has had the greatest opportunity 
 and the most favorable environment, the consensus of opinion 
 seems to favor the encouragement of small holdings. English 
 authorities maintain, as a rule, that a mixed system of large and 
 small farms is the ideal condition, but that at present the emphasis 
 should be placed on intensive farming. In 1889 a Select (British) 
 Committee on the subject recommended unanimously that " the 
 extension of a system of small holdings is a matter of national 
 importance;" and in 1892 Parliament passed the Small Holdings 
 Act which empowers county councils to purchase land and sell 
 or lease it in small holdings. Purchasers were required to pay
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 533 
 
 one fifth of the price on taking possession, and the remainder in 
 fifty years. In the beginning the Act does not appear to have been 
 a glowing success, and by 1903 only 62 small holdings, covering 
 248 acres, had been sold, and 166 holdings, covering 373 acres, 
 let. Recent amendments of the Act, however, appear to have 
 aroused more interest, and it is now asserted that, " since the pass- 
 ing of the Small Holdings Act, upwards of 47,000 small holdings 
 have been applied for in various parts of the country." * 
 
 We would not be misunderstood. A universal system of small 
 holdings would be good for no country, as a certain number of 
 large farms, assisted by abundant capital, are needed to set the 
 pace in the improvement of agricultural methods. And in the 
 United States, it is hoped, small holdings on the British scale will 
 not have to be considered for many generations, while we never 
 want the peasant farmer. But we do want the cultivation of that 
 spirit which has made Danish agriculture, in spite of great obstacles, 
 such a marvelous success; and it is imperative to avoid, if we can, 
 the growth of those conditions which have drawn so much of the 
 best rural blood of England to the cities. Both of these objects, 
 we believe, will be measurably advanced by the encouragement 
 of intensive farming. 
 
 Ownership and Tenancy. The essential facts bearing upon 
 the subject of farm ownership and tenure are summarized in 
 Table II, which is presented on the following page. 
 
 Section A of the table shows that cash and share tenancy are 
 increasing in the United States, and that the proportion of farms 
 operated by their owners was smaller in 1900 than in either 1890 
 or 1880. Two interpretations of this phenomenon have been 
 advanced. According to the first, which is based partially upon 
 the statistics cited in Section B of the table, the growth of tenancy 
 is due primarily to the increasingly rapid rise of farm laborers from 
 the position of wage earner to that of tenant. In this view, accord- 
 ingly, the increase of tenancy is encouraging. According to the 
 second interpretation, based partially upon the facts presented in 
 Sections C and E, the growth of tenancy is not an encouraging 
 
 1 The Westminster Review, May, 1908, p. 516. For the history of the legisla- 
 tion, see L. Jebb, The Small Holdings of England, Chap. IX.
 
 534 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 STATISTICS OF FARM OWNERSHIP AND FARM TENURE IN THE UNITED 
 STATES : 1880-1900 
 
 
 
 1900 
 
 1890 
 
 1880 
 
 
 (Per cent of farms operated by owners 
 
 64 7 
 
 71.6 
 
 74. e 
 
 A 
 
 Per cent of farms operated by cash tenants . . . 
 Per cent of farms operated by share tenants . . 
 
 I3-I 
 
 22.2 
 
 IO.O 
 
 18.4 
 
 8.0 
 
 17-5 
 
 
 [Per cent of males employed in agriculture : 
 Who are owners 
 
 42.3 
 
 42.0 
 
 42.2 
 
 
 Who are tenants 
 
 23 I 
 
 16.6 
 
 14. C 
 
 
 Who are laborers and others 
 
 34 6 
 
 4.1.4. 
 
 43 3. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Per cent of persons owning farm homes: 
 All ages . . 
 
 64 4 
 
 6s o 
 
 
 
 Under 25 vears 
 
 27.8 
 
 32.6 
 
 
 C H 
 
 25 to 34 years 
 
 4<?.3 
 
 40.8 
 
 
 
 3<J to 44 vears . . 
 
 64 4 
 
 64 o 
 
 
 
 4? to ?4 vears 
 
 7O 7 
 
 72 3 
 
 
 
 55 years and over 
 
 8l.4 
 
 82.2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Per cent of owners of rented farms who own : 
 i farm 
 
 800 
 
 
 
 
 2 farms 4 
 
 114 
 
 
 
 p < 
 
 3 and under 5 farms 
 
 e.A. 
 
 
 
 
 5 and under 10 farms 
 
 2.3 
 
 
 
 
 10 and under 20 farms 
 
 O 7 
 
 
 
 
 20 farms and over 
 
 O 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Per cent of farm homes owned : 
 Free 
 
 689 
 
 71.8 
 
 
 
 Encumbered 
 
 31 I 
 
 28 2 
 
 
 
 Encumbered, all ages 
 
 31 I 
 
 28.2 
 
 
 
 Encumbered, under 25 years 
 
 20 3 
 
 21.0 
 
 
 E 
 
 Encumbered, 25 to 34 years 
 
 JC C 
 
 31 
 
 
 
 Encumbered, 35 to 44 years 
 
 366 
 
 3.1 8 
 
 
 
 Encumbered, 45 to 54 years 
 
 3i.8 
 
 3O.2 
 
 
 
 Encumbered, 55 years and over 
 
 24.6 
 
 22.6 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 A, B, and D from Twelfth Census, Agriculture, Part I, pp. Ixxvii, Ixxxviii ; C and E from 
 Twelfth Census, Population, Part II, p. ccxi. The statistics under B are in the nature of 
 estimates, a small number of female owners and tenants being included under " laborers and 
 others." The aggregate percentages under A differ from those under C, owing to the fact 
 that they were collected by different departments of the census, and apply to slightly differ- 
 ent areas.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 535 
 
 sign, and indicates that it is becoming more and more difficult 
 to acquire ownership of land in this country. The statistics of 
 ownership under C prove that there is a steady movement from 
 tenancy to ownership as farmers grow older. More than 70 per 
 cent of the farmers between 45 and 54 years of age, but only 45.3 
 per cent of those between 25 and 34 years of age, owned the farms 
 which they operated in 1900. This steady advance is encouraging; 
 but the comparison of the figures for 1900 and 1890 indicates that 
 the rate of advance is declining. Moreover, the statistics presented 
 in Section E show that the proportion of owned farms which were 
 burdened with indebtedness was, for every age group, larger in 
 1900 than in 1890. 
 
 The statistics presented in Table II and the two interpretations 
 of their meaning are not, in reality, inconsistent. Tenancy is 
 more frequent in the South Central and South Atlantic states than 
 in other sections of the country, and more prevalent among negroes 
 than any other class of farmers. Here, evidently, tenancy does 
 represent an advance. The negroes who are tenants to-day were 
 farm laborers a few years ago and slaves a half century back. On 
 the other hand, tenancy is also prevalent and growing in the richest 
 farming district of the country, a district in which farm values 
 are high and advancing very rapidly; and in this district the 
 North Central states there is evidence of a close though not 
 perfect correlation between farm values and tenancy. 1 
 
 There is no cause for grave alarm concerning farm tenancy in 
 this country. Although the census of 1900 revealed one landlord 
 who owned 704 farms worth $4,545,230, Section D of Table II 
 shows that 80 per cent of the landlords owned only i rented farm, 
 and 96.8 per cent less than 5 rented farms; while the additional 
 fact that 78.8 per cent of the landlords lived in the same county 
 in which their farms were located proves that absentee landlordism 
 has not developed to any extent in this country. But we cannot 
 regard present tendencies with all the complacency exhibited by 
 some writers. 2 For not only has it been shown that the increase 
 
 1 See H. C. Taylor, Agricultural Economics, pp. 224-250. 
 
 2 See Twelfth Census, "Agriculture," Part I, pp. Ixxvii-lxxxi ; and E. L. 
 Bogart in the Journal of Political Economy for April, 1908.
 
 536 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 of tenancy in the North Central states is probably due to the in- 
 creasing difficulty of acquiring land consequent upon advancing 
 land values; but tenancy is bound to increase as land values ad- 
 vance, unless the American farmer learns how to get a living from 
 smaller holdings. When land goes to $200 an acre, the average 
 young farmer can neither save enough nor command enough 
 credit to buy a farm of 160 acres and equip it properly. We shall 
 have either more tenancy in the older sections of the country, as 
 time passes, or smaller farms and a different type of agriculture. 
 As stated above, the latter change would probably do more good 
 than harm in the land. Our only fear is that the American farmer 
 will not adjust himself to it rapidly enough. 
 
 And it is doubtful whether we ought to derive comfort from an increase 
 in the proportion of owners as shown in Section B of Table II when 
 this increase results from an exodus of the agricultural population to the 
 cities, which must itself be regarded with grave apprehension. Census 
 officials explain away the increase of tenancy by dividing the agricultural 
 class into three reservoirs, owners, tenants, and others (presumably 
 laborers), and assure us that the swelling volume of the middle reservoir 
 is due to an increasingly rapid flow from the labor reservoir to the tenant 
 reservoir, rather than a decreasingly rapid flow from the tenant reservoir to 
 the reservoir of owners. But what about the flow from the labor reservoir to 
 non-agricultural occupations ? And how much of the diminution of owner- 
 ship in trade and manufactures should be charged against the increase of 
 ownership in agriculture? It is a condition, not a theory, confronting us, 
 and when we start to explain this condition, it is not permissible to halt 
 midway in the explanation. 1 
 
 Farm Labor. Although the agricultural account, to use a 
 bookkeeper's metaphor, must be debited with any evil resulting 
 from the rural exodus, before we can strike a proper balance of 
 social profit and loss, the condition of those laborers who have 
 remained upon the farms has unquestionably been improved by 
 
 1 Two other agricultural problems of great importance might logically be in- 
 troduced here share versus cash tenancy and a consideration of the conditions 
 under which it is better for a young farmer to hire than attempt to buy a farm. 
 The latter problem is considered in connection with other relevant questions on 
 page 540 of this chapter. The former question involves a discussion of the de- 
 tails of farm leases, and must be left to the larger treatises, although we may 
 venture the suggestion that more depends upon the customs and conditions of 
 peculiar localities than upon any inherent superiority of the cash rental.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 
 
 537 
 
 this exodus. The movement of the wages of farm labor since 
 the Civil War is described statistically in Table III, following. 
 From this it appears that farm wages were higher in the last 
 
 TABLE III 
 
 WAGES OF FARM LABOR IN THE UNITED STATES FOR SPECIFIED YEARS: 
 
 1866-1902 
 
 (Wages expressed in currency for the years 1866, 1869, 1875) 
 
 
 PER MONTH 
 FOR YEAR OR 
 
 PER DAY 
 IN HARVEST 
 
 ORDINARY 
 FARM LABOR 
 
 RELATIVE WAGES 
 PER MONTH WITH 
 BOARD ON THE 
 
 
 SEASON 
 
 
 PER DAY 
 
 
 YEAR 
 
 
 
 
 BASIS OF 1800 
 
 
 Without 
 
 With 
 
 Without 
 
 With 
 
 Without 
 
 With 
 
 Money 
 
 Real 
 
 
 board 
 
 board 
 
 board 
 
 board 
 
 board 
 
 board 
 
 wages 
 
 wages 
 
 1902 
 
 $22.14 
 
 $16.40 
 
 *i-53 
 
 $1.34 
 
 $1.13 
 
 $.89 
 
 I3I-7 
 
 121. 6 
 
 1899 
 
 20.23 
 
 14.07 
 
 J -37 
 
 1. 12 
 
 I.OI 
 
 77 
 
 113.0 
 
 116.3 
 
 1898 
 
 19.38 
 
 *3-43 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.0 5 
 
 .96 
 
 .72 
 
 107.9 
 
 111.9 
 
 1895 
 
 17.69 
 
 I2.O2 
 
 1.14 
 
 .92 
 
 .81 
 
 .62 
 
 96-5 
 
 IOI.O 
 
 1894 
 
 J7-74 
 
 12. l6 
 
 1-13 
 
 93 
 
 .81 
 
 63 
 
 97-7 
 
 100.3 
 
 1893 
 
 19.10 
 
 13.29 
 
 1.24 
 
 1.03 
 
 .89 
 
 .69 
 
 106.7 
 
 104.7 
 
 1892 
 
 18.60 
 
 12-54 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.02 
 
 .92 
 
 .67 
 
 100.7 
 
 IOI.2 
 
 1890 
 
 i8-33 
 
 12.45 
 
 1.30 
 
 I.O2 
 
 .92 
 
 .68 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 1888 
 
 18.24 
 
 12.36 
 
 i-3i 
 
 I. O2 
 
 .92 
 
 .67 
 
 99-3 
 
 96.7 
 
 1885 
 
 17.97 
 
 12.34 
 
 1.40 
 
 I.IO 
 
 .91 
 
 .67 
 
 99.1 
 
 99-5 
 
 1882 
 
 18.94 
 
 12.41 
 
 1.48 
 
 "5" 
 
 93 
 
 .67 
 
 99-7 
 
 85-7 
 
 1879 
 
 16.42 
 
 10.43 
 
 1.30 
 
 1. 00 
 
 .81 
 
 59 
 
 83.8 
 
 82.6 
 
 1875 
 
 19.87 
 
 12.72 
 
 1.70 
 
 i-35 
 
 i. 08 
 
 78 
 
 IO2.2 
 
 74-3 
 
 1869 
 
 25.92 
 
 16.55 
 
 2. 2O 
 
 1.74 
 
 1.41 
 
 1.02 
 
 132.9 
 
 81.8 
 
 1866 
 
 26.87 
 
 17-45 
 
 2. 2O 
 
 1.74 
 
 1.49 
 
 1. 08 
 
 I4O.2 
 
 70.0 
 
 NOTE. Broad averages are particularly unsatisfactory in dealing with the wages of farm 
 labor, and the reader should regard this table not as an exact exhibit of money wages, but as a 
 compendious method of describing a social movement the details of which are beyond the 
 scope of this treatise. For a more adequate discussion, see Bulletin No. 26, Miscellaneous 
 Series, U. S. Department of Agriculture. 
 
 year for which statistics are available than ever before, if we 
 properly discount the inflated currency in which wages were paid 
 in 1866, 1869, and 1875; and the rough estimates of the purchasing 
 power of farm wages given in the last column of the table indicate 
 that real wages have steadily risen since 1866. Moreover, the testi-
 
 538 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 mony is practically unanimous to the effect that the increased use 
 of farm machinery has not only reduced the hours of labor, but 
 has diversified and lightened the toil of the farm hand. Added 
 to these evidences of increasing material comfort is the reassuring 
 fact that the farm hand retains, in a large degree, his superior 
 social position. The native white farm laborer usually eats at 
 the, same table with his employer, shares his social diversions, and 
 in general mixes in the same social class on terms of approximate 
 equality. 
 
 There is room, however, for much improvement. The hours of 
 labor are still long in the country, 10 in winter, 12 in summer, 
 13 in harvest season on the average, and, except on a very small 
 number of farms, there are two or three months in the year when 
 the laborer cannot secure full work. " The able-bodied, industrious 
 man desirous of employing his full vigor continuously finds a limi- 
 tation in the average condition of farming. Seedtime and harvest 
 make busy their respective periods, but whenever the frost of winter 
 or the drought of summer suspend the activity of vegetation, there 
 will be an interval in the work of the cultivator." 1 
 
 Furthermore, the best evidence obtainable supports the con- 
 clusion that while " skilled labor, owing to its contact with ma- 
 chinery and the influence of education, has attained increased 
 efficiency," " unskilled and irregular labor has lost much of its for- 
 mer adaptability and value to the farm." 2 Worst of all, there is 
 rapidly developing a class of migratory or casual agricultural 
 laborers who drift from city to country and back again, who have 
 no ambition to establish themselves permanently upon the land, 
 and yet teach the farmer to rely upon their assistance, and debase 
 the real standard of living of the laborer who adopts farming as 
 a serious occupation, and looks forward to the acquisition some 
 day of a farm of his own. 
 
 Farm Indebtedness and Agricultural Credit. The favorite 
 instrument by which landownership is achieved in this country 
 is the farm mortgage. In 1890, 18.60 per cent of all farm families 
 
 1 J. H. Blodgett, Wages of Farm Labor in the United States, p. 25. Bulletin No. 
 26, Miscellaneous Series, U.S. Department of Agriculture, p. 25. 
 * Final Report of the Industrial Commission, p. 92.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 
 
 539 
 
 occupied encumbered homes; 35.55 per cent of the value of these 
 farms was covered by indebtedness, on which an interest rate of 
 7.07 per cent per annum was paid; 64.38 per cent of this indebted- 
 ness was contracted for the purpose of buying the farms; 83.51 
 per cent for buying, stocking, and equipping the farms; and 
 probably not more than 5 or 6 per cent (something between 2.83 
 per cent and 12.35 P er cent) represented losses and household 
 expenses or "unproductive consumption." The farm mortgage, 
 accordingly, is not necessarily a bad thing. It is, in census phrase- 
 ology, " a mere business venture," and in this country has proved 
 a successful venture in a surprisingly large proportion of cases. 
 Since the financial depression of 1893-1897, particularly, farm 
 mortgages have been paid off with unusual rapidity. 
 
 In European countries, particularly on the continent, a great 
 deal of legislation has been enacted for the purpose of developing 
 agricultural credit; and cooperative credit associations, particu- 
 larly the German Landschaften, have played an important part 
 in enabling farmers to obtain the capital necessary to purchase and 
 equip farms. In principle these associations are not unlike the 
 American building and loan societies. They operate within 
 limited districts, lend their funds at the lowest rate consistent with 
 safety, compel borrowers to liquidate the principal of their loans 
 regularly as they make their interest payments, teach farmers how 
 to work together for common ends, and offer in their shares or 
 bonds a safe investment both for the thrifty young farmer whose 
 savings are not large enough to be lent in the form of an ordinary 
 mortgage, and for the retired farmer who desires to be rid of the 
 trouble of leasing and looking after his land. 
 
 At the present time it would be unwise to introduce into this 
 country land banks, Raiffeisen credit banks, district credit associa- 
 tions or any other exotic credit agency, merely for the purpose of 
 multiplying credit facilities. 
 
 Notwithstanding this truth, however, it would be a happy 
 augury for this country if the cooperative credit association took 
 root in our farming districts and flourished there; because the 
 spirit that generates and sustains them is an invaluable social asset, 
 and once under way such associations help to strengthen and prop-
 
 540 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 agate that spirit. While, therefore, it might be unwise at this time 
 to transplant such associations to this country or assist them by 
 state aid, 1 it would be the height of wisdom to stimulate the love 
 of agriculture, the atmosphere of thrift and mutual aid in which 
 such associations thrive. For they might possibly reduce the 
 interest rate in farming districts if they got a foothold there; and 
 they would almost certainly provide farmers with a better form 
 of investing their savings than they now have, facilitate the sale 
 of land, and hence increase ownership as opposed to tenancy, 
 compel borrowers to pay the principal of their debt gradually as 
 they made the interest payments, and above all train the farming 
 population in habits of cooperative endeavor and in the wise use 
 of that double-edged sword, credit. After all our need is not for 
 more credit but for a wiser use of credit. The good that might 
 be accomplished in the South by introducing cooperative credit 
 in the place of the crop-lien system is almost inconceivable. And 
 in the first analysis, at least, such a project does not appear to be 
 hopeless, for the South is much stronger in almost every way 
 to-day than was devastated Silesia when the first Landschaft 
 began operations in 1770. 
 
 Tenancy versus Encumbered Ownership. We are now in 
 position to discuss profitably the question when and where if 
 ever tenancy is to be preferred to land ownership. For though 
 it may come as a surprise to some American readers, many foreign 
 authorities of the highest rank strongly advocate tenancy in pref- 
 erence to ownership when land has become very valuable. In the 
 expert evidence given before the British committee of 1906 on 
 small holdings, for instance, the balance of opinion seems to have 
 inclined toward tenancy rather than ownership. 
 
 Here again we meet one of those mixed economic and psycho- 
 logical questions to which no simple answer can be given. In a 
 frontier or newly settled community, there is, of course, little reason 
 for tenancy from any standpoint. But in an old community, 
 where land values are high and are as likely to fluctuate down- 
 
 1 However, the German Landschaften owe their origin to the investigations and 
 support of Frederick the Great, although the details of the system were first 
 worked out by the Berlin merchant, Biihring. See the Agrarisches Handbuch 
 of the Bund der Landwirte, pp. 557-558.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 541 
 
 wards as upwards in the next score of years or so, the economic 
 arguments in favor of tenancy are exceedingly strong if not alto- 
 gether convincing, (a) Under such circumstances the farmer 
 who insists upon holding the title to the land which he tills must 
 either go deeply into debt, or understock his farm, or both. To 
 underequip the farm means poor agriculture; and a heavy debt 
 hangs like a millstone around the neck of a farmer when land 
 values are not on the increase. The tenant farmers of England 
 have had a far more pleasant time since 1873 than the small land- 
 owning farmers whose holdings were encumbered with debt at 
 that time, (b) The ownership of land throws upon the farmer 
 all the speculative responsibilities of the entrepreneur, and other 
 things being equal if they can ever be regarded as equal it is 
 desirable for the man of small means to avoid these responsibilities. 
 The tenant system offers a means of insurance against some of 
 these risks, (c) Such insurance becomes all the more advan- 
 tageous and encumbered ownership all the more disadvantageous 
 because of the well-known fact that land yields a net return, year 
 by year, lower than almost any other form of property. Part of 
 this is due to the social prestige of landownership and part to the 
 fact that over very long periods the small annual profit on land is 
 likely to be compensated for by an increase in the capital value of 
 the land. Under such circumstances landownership is partly a 
 luxury and partly a method of saving, usually for the descendants 
 and heirs of the saver. Both factors conspire to make land a 
 poor investment for the man of small means. He cannot afford 
 luxuries, on the one hand, and he must find a method of business, 
 on the other hand, that yields him a quick return, (d) And 
 finally, it must be noted that the question of tenancy is not like 
 the labor problem which has developed in the factory industries. 
 The tenant is not a wage-earner. He may be as independent as 
 the manufacturer who hires the land, buildings, and possibly the 
 machinery with which he works. The problem of tenancy, there- 
 fore, has no necessary relationship to the problem created by the 
 existence of a class of permanent wage-earners. The small entre- 
 preneur still holds the field in agriculture, all over the world. The 
 question is simply: shall he hire his plant or own it?
 
 542 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Notwithstanding the fact that tenant farming may go hand in 
 hand, as it does in England, with good farming, and notwithstand- 
 ing the desirability of reducing the speculative risks of an industry 
 which is at best much too uncertain, the problem can never be 
 settled on economic grounds alone ; and if we add to the economic 
 virtues of ownership its social and moral advantages, the final 
 verdict must be rendered against tenancy. Ownership not only 
 spurs the zeal of the farmer, dignifies his occupation, and inculcates 
 a love of the soil which nothing else inspires in so great a degree, 
 but it gives the farmer a stake in the political game, steadies him. 
 and thus improves his citizenship. It is perfectly plain that owner- 
 ship cannot be enforced upon a people that are not prepared for it : 
 certain restricted districts of the South in which negro ownership 
 prevailed a few years ago, we understand on good authority, are 
 now relapsing into quasi-barbarism. And it is equally obvious 
 that the virtues which go with ownership may and often do de- 
 generate into vices: the peasant proprietor's love of the soil occa- 
 sionally becomes land worship, his thrift avarice, his conservatism 
 blind fear, and his industry cruel he drives himself and wife 
 and children at a pace that would put the sweater to shame. 
 
 But we are not advocating the extension of landownership 
 through state aid we simply call attention to the desirability 
 of fostering those qualities which lead to the diffusion of ownership 
 and are in turn strengthened by ownership ; and we maintain that 
 the American people at present are in no danger of excessive thrift 
 or of the sordid materialism of peasant proprietorship at its worst. 
 The tendencies and the dangers are almost all in the opposite 
 direction. If, in the next fifty years, the farmers of the Middle 
 West become predominantly tenants, it will not be because tenancy 
 is economically and socially superior to ownership, but because the 
 farmers of that district have not had the thrift to save and the 
 ability to adapt themselves to more intensive agriculture. And 
 the step will be backward, not forward. The popular instinct 
 which in this country causes an increase of tenancy to be regarded 
 with distrust is a sound instinct. 
 
 A minor disadvantage of tenancy is found in the fact that tenancy, when it 
 becomes predominant, raises difficulties that can only be met by constant
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 543 
 
 State interference. Short leases with no indemnification to the tenant for 
 the improvements which he has made, lead to rack-renting, exhaustion of the 
 soil, and class hatred between landlords and tenants. Long leases, on the 
 other hand, afford insufficient protection to the landlord; because when 
 prices are high the tenant thrives and pays his rent promptly, but when 
 prices fall rents go unpaid and the landlord has no real redress. In England 
 the situation has been met by a system of short time leases together with 
 compensation to the tenant a legal obligation which the landlord cannot 
 escape by "contracting out" for any improvement made by the tenant 
 whose value he has not exhausted. Neither party can abrogate a lease 
 without a year's notice, although by mutual consent this may be reduced to 
 six months. This system permits rentals to be adjusted frequently as prices 
 change, rules out excessive competition, protects the landlord, and warrants 
 the tenant in making any improvement required by good farming, since he 
 knows that, if the landlord orders him out, he can collect on his departure 
 the actual value of improvements made by him, whose benefits he has not 
 had time to reap. In practice, the incoming tenant usually pays for the un- 
 exhausted improvements, and disputes are settled by arbitration. Under 
 this system, "the relation between landlord and tenant is very satisfactorily 
 arranged, the farmers are, as a rule, contented with the present system, and 
 the fields of England prove that landownership on the part of farmers is not 
 essential to good agriculture." l 
 
 Marketing of Farm Products. One of our most urgent needs 
 at the present time is the greater diversification of industry in 
 general. The prices of the great staple crops such as wheat are 
 largely dependent upon conditions of demand and supply in for- 
 eign markets; and the consequence is that a poor crop may coin- 
 cide with a period of low prices, or an abnormally large crop with 
 unusually high prices. This is almost impossible in the case of 
 products whose value is fixed in a local market. With such prod- 
 ucts, the misfortune of a small yield is normally reduced by the 
 advantage to the producer of a high price ; the two com- 
 pensating factors working to moderate those fluctuations of income 
 which are the bane of the agricultural industry. The advantage 
 is not all with the local market. Prices are apt to be steadier in a 
 world market, because the latter reflects conditions over a wider 
 area. For this reason it would be unwise to endanger our foreign 
 markets by tariff wars or oppressive railway regulation. But 
 such pressure as can legitimately be exerted at the present time 
 
 1 H. C. Taylor, The Decline of Landowning Farmers in England, p. 61.
 
 544 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 should be employed to bring the miller, the brewer, the cotton 
 manufacturer, the packer, and the consumer closer to the farm. 
 If caution and expert knowledge are employed, this can be done 
 without crippling those transportation agencies which have given 
 the American farmer entry to the markets of Europe and the 
 Orient, and which must be preserved in order to prevent too exclu- 
 sive a reliance upon local demand. A local market as the regular 
 outlet, and a foreign market as a potential outlet, is the condition 
 of maximum safety. 
 
 Railway tariffs which favor through traffic at the expense of 
 local traffic are largely if not mainly responsible for the concen- 
 tration of manufactures and population in the large cities. For 
 many years, Southern cotton mills reaped little or no advantage, 
 so far as the price of cotton was concerned, from their proximity 
 to the source of supply, but paid as much or even more for cotton 
 than their competitors in New York. The railways are not wholly 
 responsible for this condition of affairs. In England, particularly, 
 representatives of the agricultural interests have criticised the rail- 
 ways for accepting lower rates from the seaboard to interior points, 
 than on local traffic from intervening stations to the same desti- 
 nation, when the difference was fully explained by the larger 
 size of the seaboard shipments, their more convenient package, 
 and the great expense of picking up small consignments of freight 
 at numerous local way stations. And competition forces railways 
 frequently to accept lower rates for long than for short hauls over 
 the same road. But there can be little doubt that American rail- 
 ways have charged the local traffic much more than their necessity 
 compelled them to charge, particularly in the South; and there are 
 few reforms on the side of marketing which American farmers 
 could demand with more equity or secure with greater social profit 
 than the rehabilitation and revitalization of the long and short 
 haul clause of the Interstate Commerce Act, emasculated by the 
 Supreme Court decision in the Alabama Midland Case (168 U.S. 
 144, 173). This might, however, involve certain pains of read- 
 justment. 
 
 At present there is a great gap between the farmer and the con- 
 sumer of his products which is bridged by a complicated trad-
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 545 
 
 ing or distributive * mechanism composed of railways, storage 
 companies, commission merchants, brokers, and other middlemen. 
 In the distribution of the great staple products, the commission 
 merchant is rapidly being forced out, and fortunately so: he was 
 unprogressive, uneconomical, and too often betrayed the interests 
 of his client by systematic overcharges for insurance, hauling, and 
 storage, by buying consignments on his own account when market 
 conditions were unusually favorable, and selling at the loss of the 
 owner when the market was particularly bad. In the marketing 
 of perishable goods the commission system has a more tenacious 
 hold, but even here it has been partly replaced by cooperative 
 associations of farmers or growers such as the California Fruit 
 Growers and Shippers' Association, which maintains auction 
 rooms in eastern cities and sells its own products direct. The 
 Southern California Fruit Exchange, to cite a single illustration, 
 in a few years'reduced the cost of marketing California fruits from 
 10 to 3 per cent of the sales value. 
 
 The cooperative marketing association and the intermediate 
 trader who buys from the grower and sells to the consumer, have 
 in common two points of superiority over the commission system; 
 (a) they replace the zeal of an agent by the care and solicitude of 
 an owner; (b) and by shipping in large quantities they are in posi- 
 tion to obtain much better rates from the railways, to say nothing 
 of the other economics affected by handling goods on a large scale. 2 
 Whether the cooperative association will force the commission 
 merchant out of business in the marketing of fruits and vegetables 
 is a point which cannot be settled here. But there can be little 
 doubt that the farmer has gained enormously by the substitution 
 of the trader for the commission house in the marketing of the great 
 staple products. The trader comes almost to the door of the 
 farmer, with constant bids for his grain. He is an expert in rail- 
 way rates, in constant telegraphic communication with the great 
 markets of the world, and handles products in such large quantities 
 
 1 The word "distributive" is used in the popular sense in this chapter. 
 
 2 The cooperative marketing associations have also effected great economies 
 by watching prices in all markets carefully and distributing their consignments 
 so as to get the highest prices obtaining at the time. 
 
 2N
 
 546 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 as to reduce intermediate expenses to a minimum. Occasionally, 
 as has sometimes been the case with the great line elevator com- 
 panies, he works in conjunction or in collusion with the railways, 
 overbidding the small grain dealer, and forcing the railway to 
 grant rebates on the large shipments which he commands. Even 
 in this case, the farmer gains by the size and efficiency of the 
 middleman (though the small dealer may suffer) because part of 
 the economies effected even those effected by the discriminative 
 railway rates will come to him in the long run. Cases of mo- 
 nopolistic oppression are theoretically possible when there is only 
 one buyer and one railway who are in collusion, and the farmer 
 is deprived because of high railway rates from shipping his 
 products elsewhere. But the loss to the farmer through extortion 
 of this kind has in general been much more than counterbalanced 
 by the striking economies effected by the great trading companies; 
 though this, of course, affords no justification either* for monopoly 
 or railway discrimination. Both should be suppressed, if possible ; 
 but in such a way as to save for the farmer the distributive econo- 
 mies effected by large-scale handling. 
 
 Speculation. The modern marketing or distributive mechan- 
 ism not only relieves the producer of a large part of the specula- 
 tive risk which attends the transmission of raw material from the 
 farm to the consumer, and calls public attention to this speculative 
 element by collecting or concentrating it, but it is responsible also 
 for a large amount of unnecessary speculation which many persons 
 believe to be particularly injurious to the farmer. We are not here 
 concerned with the general evils of speculation but with the 
 prevalent belief that dealing in options and futures tends to re- 
 duce prices. " What is generally urged is that the professional 
 short seller, by his sales of fictitious wheat or cotton, creates a 
 fictitious oversupply in the market, which is just as instrumental 
 in depressing prices as would be an abnormally large supply of 
 actual wheat thrown on the market by the farmer." l This charge 
 is frequently supplemented by the assertion that it requires less 
 money in margins to " sell short " or gamble on a fall in 
 
 1 N. I. Stone in the Report of the Industrial Commission, Vol. VI, p. 189 ff., 
 from which the other quotations cited in this section are also taken.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 547 
 
 prices than to " sell long " in anticipation of a rise, and that, 
 in consequence, the weight of the speculative dealing in farm 
 products is exerted in the direction of lower prices. 
 
 This particular charge against speculation is confirmed neither 
 by a priori reasoning nor by inductive analysis. Every " ficti- 
 tious " sale of wheat, to use that as an illustration, must be balanced 
 by an equivalent " fictitious " purchase. The " bear " who sells 
 October wheat in July, even though he may hope to depress the 
 price of October " futures," exercises no harmful influence upon 
 the actual July or " spot " price, which is controlled by the demand 
 for and supply of actual wheat; and when October comes, " the 
 short seller of July appears now as a buyer in order to cover his 
 contracts, and if his trading has any effect on the market at all, 
 it is to increase the demand, not the supply." 
 
 It is very plain that the fictitious market may be artificially 
 influenced by speculative deals, but as a general thing the fictitious 
 market is ruled by the actual market, not vice versa ; and the only 
 influence exerted by gambling in futures upon " spot " prices (with 
 which alone the farmer is concerned) is a good influence. This 
 influence arises out of the effect of future transactions in equalizing 
 consumption and in modifying present use by anticipating future 
 necessity. And the complaint that it requires less capital to " bear " 
 the market than to " bull " it, as well as a great number of ingen- 
 ious criticisms of a similar kind, would all be negatived if they 
 were true by the inevitable consequence that any permanent 
 factor of this kind would be quickly appreciated by speculators and 
 fully discounted. In no market are influences of this kind so 
 accurately detected and so quickly dissipated by competitive 
 forces as on the produce and cotton exchanges. 
 
 Actual investigations of prices confirm the theoretical argument 
 made above. The average prices of spot wheat in September, 
 October, and November just after harvest, when the ordinary 
 farmer is compelled to sell have been nearer the average price 
 for the entire year, since the wheat market has become highly 
 speculative, than it was in the forties and fifties when wheat was 
 sold like any other farm product. And there are reasons for the 
 belief that speculation has not only equalized yearly fluctuations,
 
 548 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 but that the leveling has been up, not down, in the interest of the 
 farmer who is compelled to sell after harvest, as opposed to the 
 wealthier miller or trader who in the past carried over a supply 
 for the lean months. "It is not uncommonly stated that in the 
 last few years futures in the wheat market have not, in the long 
 run, stood enough above " spots " to cover all the expenses of 
 carrying. Some suggested reasons for this are: cut charges for 
 storage; the failure of outside speculation to maintain the market 
 against hedging sales; the fact that the great elevators will buy 
 wheat and carry it for what they can get, and perform the functions 
 of both carrier and trader for the commission of one. In any case, 
 the tendency is to bring all prices together." 1 
 
 Education and Organization. Again and again, in studying 
 the problems of agriculture, we come back to the conclusion that 
 the real evils which beset agriculture are to be remedied not merely 
 by destroying monopoly, and still less by suppressing speculation, 
 or increasing the money supply, but by education, using that 
 word in its most catholic sense. The laws that are worth passing, 
 the customs that are worth introducing, the institutions that are 
 worth establishing, are those that educate, though curiously 
 enough most of these require for their realization a preliminary 
 campaign of education. In the final analysis, agricultural better- 
 ment comes back to the will and ideals of the individual farmer, 
 and the supreme value of education lies in its power to prick the 
 ambition, energize the will, and awaken the pride of the farmer. 
 
 It would be impossible, within the limits of this chapter, to dis- 
 cuss the subject of agricultural education; and the reader is doubt- 
 less familiar with the work done by the United States Department 
 of Agriculture and the experiment stations, the agricultural colleges 
 and their traveling lecturers, farmers' institutes, farmers' bulle- 
 tins, and short (winter) courses for working farmers. Scientific 
 research and agricultural education of the more advanced type 
 are now fairly well provided for. The urgent demand at present 
 is for better education of the elementary and secondary grades. 
 The public expenditures for research and advanced education that 
 
 1 H. C. Emery, Speculation on the Stock and Produce Exchanges of the United 
 States, p. 131.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 549 
 
 have been made in the past have been richly remunerative. Simi- 
 lar appropriations for elementary instruction in agriculture would 
 probably prove even more profitable. Above all, the district 
 school should be improved, and interest in agriculture awakened 
 by the intelligent introduction of nature study and rudimentary 
 agriculture. The country must learn to interest and keep the high- 
 est talent which it produces, instead of packing off the brightest 
 boys to the cities. And above the district school, institutions of a 
 higher grade must be developed, in which agriculture shall occupy 
 the same place that manual training does in the best of our city 
 trade schools. 
 
 "To bridge the institutional gap between the public schools and the agri- 
 cultural college there is nothing in the American system of agricultural 
 education corresponding in completeness to that in operation in France. 
 There agricultural education begins in the rural primary schools, from the 
 ages of 7 to 9, with the simplest facts of agriculture, such as first lessons in the 
 garden ; from 9 to 1 1 years, soils, fertilizers, tillage, and the ordinary imple- 
 ments; from ii to 13 years, more methodical instruction, in tillage, drainage, 
 implements, fertilizers, sowing, harvesting, domestic animals, horticultural 
 propagation, tree culture, and grafting. After 13, advanced courses for 
 boys and girls include practical ideas and operations in the leading phases 
 of agriculture. The rural primary schools have about 3400 gardens attached 
 to them. There are 160 of the superior primary schools, with more than 
 15,000 pupils receiving instruction in agriculture." l 
 
 9 
 
 "The farm problem," it has been truly said, "consists in 
 maintaining upon our farms a class of people who have succeeded 
 in procuring for themselves the highest possible class status, not 
 only in the industrial, but in the political and social order a 
 relative status, moreover, that is measured by the demands of 
 American ideals." 2 To secure and maintain such a status, edu- 
 cation in the ordinary sense is not enough. Education must be 
 supplemented by a multitude of social organizations, quickening, 
 enlightening, and solidifying the agricultural classes. A great 
 variety of such organizations are already in the field, from the 
 county teachers" and patrons' associations designed to unite pupil, 
 
 1 Final Report of the Industrial Commission, p. 130. 
 
 2 K. L. Butterfield, President of the Massachusetts Agricultural College, 
 Chapters in Rural Progress, p. 15.
 
 550 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 teacher, and parent in a crusade for broader and deeper culture, 
 to organizations like the Patrons of Husbandry, whose first aim, 
 as enumerated in its Declaration of Purposes, is "to develop a 
 better and higher manhood and womanhood among ourselves." 
 Limitations of space forbid any extended description of the vitally 
 important work which organizations of this kind are doing for the 
 agricultural classes; but it may be possible, in conclusion, to 
 correct one or two misapprehensions which are widely prevalent 
 concerning the nature and vitality of farmers' organizations. The 
 National Grange will serve as a good illustration. 
 
 Founded just after the Civil War (1867) in order " to restore 
 kindly feelings " between the people of the North and the South, 
 this organization is still strong and vigorous, having in 1905 more 
 than 220,000 members in the five leading Grange states. Despite 
 a popular impression that the Grange is a partisan political organ- 
 ization, addicted to radical ideas and Utopian schemes of reform, 
 its principal activities are social and educational in the best sense, 
 and discussion of political or religious questions at its meetings 
 is prohibited by the organic law of the order. "It is based on 
 correct principles: organization, cooperation, education. It is 
 neither a political party nor a business agency. It is progressively 
 conservative or conservatively progressive. It is neither ultra- 
 radical nor fo/ever in the rut. Its chief work is on cultural lines. 
 It includes the entire family. It is now growing, and there is 
 every reason for thinking that this growth is of a permanent 
 character." 1 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Make a list of the economic factors which regulate the size of farms. 
 Is the average farm likely to grow larger or smaller with the passage of time ? 
 Is the narrow economic conclusion concerning the size of the farm, based upon 
 maximum net profit to the individual farmer, subject to modification by 
 reason of social or moral considerations ? 
 
 2. Has the net effect of the rural exodus been favorable or unfavorable 
 to agriculture and the agricultural classes ? to society generally ? 
 
 3. Does the increase of tenancy in the Southern states represent progress 
 or retrogression ? in the North Central states ? 
 
 4. Under what conditions is the cash rental superior to share tenancy? 
 
 1 Ibid., p. 161.
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS 551 
 
 Would the "corn rent" or a sliding rental varying with the price of farm 
 products be superior to both ? Are short leases better than long leases 
 for the landlord ? 
 
 5. Do the farmers in your locality suffer from the lack of credit facilities? 
 Have they any difficulty in finding safe and convenient investments for their 
 savings ? 
 
 6. What is the advantage of specialized farming over diversified farming? 
 Do we imply, when we advocate diversified farming, that the farmer should 
 "buy nothing that he can raise or make for himself " ? 
 
 7. Is speculation a "necessary" or an "unnecessary evil"? Do the 
 farmers suffer more or less than other classes from speculation on the produce 
 exchanges ? 
 
 8. Is any attention paid to agriculture in the elementary schools of your 
 locality ? Would large public expenditures for the improvement of ele- 
 mentary education probably prove profitable in the long run ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BUTTERFIELD, K. L. Chapters in Rural Progress. 
 
 Eleventh Census. " Real Estate Mortgages : Farms and Homes, Pro- 
 prietorship and Indebtedness." 
 
 Twelfth Census, Vol. V. Agriculture. Special Reports, Supplementary 
 Analysis, "The Negro Farmer," pp. 511-579. 
 
 DICKSON, ADAM. The Husbandry of the Ancients. 
 
 HAGGARD, H. RIDER. Rural England. 
 
 JEBB, L. The Small Holdings of England. 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics (5th ed.), Book VI, Chap. X. 
 
 MILL, J. S. Principles of Political Economy, Book II, Chaps. VI-X. 
 
 PROTHERO, R. E. The Pioneers and Progress of English Farming. 
 
 Publications of the U.S. Department of Agriculture. Year Book, The Crop 
 Reporter. 
 
 Report of the Industrial Commission, Vols. VI, X, XI, and XIX, pp. 43-200. 
 
 ROGERS, A. S. L. The Business Side of Agriculture. 
 
 ROGERS, J. E. T. History of Agriculture and Prices in England. 
 
 TAYLOR, H. C. Agricultural Economics, and " The Decline of Landowning 
 Farmers in England," Bulletin of the University of Wisconsin, No. 96.
 
 BOOK III 
 PUBLIC FINANCE
 
 CHAPTER XXXH 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 
 
 Introductory. Nature and Significance of Public Finance. 
 
 Public finance deals with the revenues of government, with their 
 expenditure and their administration. Public finance is one part 
 of economics. Like general economics, it deals with the means 
 for the satisfaction of human wants. Some of our wants we sat- 
 isfy in one way, some in another. Some we satisfy individually. 
 Some we satisfy through private associated effort, especially 
 through the private corporation. Others we satisfy through 
 public collective effort, that is to say, through some governmental 
 agency. The wants which we satisfy through governmental 
 agency are not all of them so peculiar that they could not be sat- 
 isfied either through private individual activity or private asso- 
 ciated activity. Let us take the case of watering the streets. 
 There are places in which the streets, in so far as they are watered 
 at all, are watered by individuals in their private capacity, each 
 man watering the street in front of his own house with his own 
 hose. There are other places in which the householders join 
 together and pay some one to water the streets for them, and do 
 this privately. There are still other cities in which the city gov- 
 ernment employs persons to water the streets and pays them from 
 the proceeds of taxation. 
 
 There are, to be sure, some wants which are satisfied through 
 governmental agency and which a civilized community will not 
 allow us to satisfy privately. This is the case with those wants 
 which are satisfied by means of the police and the courts. It is a 
 peculiar function of government in modern times to provide the 
 inestimable blessing that we call security of person and property. 
 This requires economic resources, just as the satisfaction of the 
 
 555
 
 556 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 other wants mentioned does, and public finance has to do with 
 the provision of these resources. 
 
 Public finance, then, is a part of economics because it deals 
 with the satisfaction of wants through economic resources. It is 
 also a part of economics because it has its influence upon the pro- 
 duction, the distribution, and the consumption of wealth. But 
 while we have to insist that public finance belongs to eco- 
 nomics, it is more separated from the other parts of economics 
 than they are from each other. Inasmuch as it deals with the 
 satisfaction of wants through governmental agency, it has its own 
 peculiarities, and it is only an undue emphasis upon these pecul- 
 iarities which leads some writers to make it a separate science. 
 
 The significance of public finance may be brought before us; 
 first, by examination of the increasing amount of public revenues, 
 and second, by the enormous aggregate of these revenues at the 
 present time. Public revenues have gone on increasing during 
 the present century by leaps and bounds. An illustration is 
 afforded by the history of France. Eighty years ago the public 
 expenditures of France reached one thousand million francs for 
 the first time, or, as we generally say, a billion francs. There was 
 universal astonishment and alarm, just as there was when, for the 
 first time, an American Congress spent a billion dollars in two 
 years. Never since the time, however, when the public expendi- 
 tures of France first amounted to a thousand million francs have 
 they been so small. Gradually they increased until they reached 
 two thousand millions, never to pass below that mark; then they 
 increased until they touched three thousand millions; and now 
 the national expenditures are nearly four thousand millions. 
 Public expenditures at the present time, under the modern 
 government, amount to more than a tenth part of all the wealth 
 produced. 1 
 
 1 This estimate (that public expenditures equal one tenth part of all the wealth 
 annually produced) has been given, but it must be a very considerable under- 
 estimate for the modern nation. We in reality know very little about the amount 
 of wealth annually produced in the modern nations of the world. But such data 
 as we have, and familiar observation, are sufficient to convince us that the wealth 
 produced is not ten times the total public expenditures. In the United States, 
 according to the Report of the Census Office, Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, the
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 557 
 
 Now what does this mean ? Does it signify increasing extrava- 
 gance or even corruption ? Quite the contrary. While the mod- 
 ern government is far from perfect, it is throughout the civilized 
 world probably better than it ever has been before. Taking the 
 civilized world as a whole, there probably never was more honest 
 government or more efficient government than there is to-day. 
 What it really means is this : We are living in a period of increas- 
 ing public cooperation. We think we find it more advantageous 
 to satisfy certain wants, growing in number and significance, 
 through public cooperation, than through individual effort or pri- 
 vate cooperation. This is the chief significance of the increasing 
 governmental budget throughout the civilized world. But un- 
 happily, militarism in its various phases is next in significance, 
 and is the chief phase of public expenditures that is disquieting. 1 
 Educational expenditures afford a good illustration. They 
 run up into the hundred millions in the modern nation, whereas, 
 previously to this century, they were insignificant. Expenditures 
 for police protection, for public lighting, and for sanitation are 
 something which, so far as any expenditures of magnitude are 
 concerned, belongs to this century. 
 
 Public finance has another significance. Questions of social 
 reform are now connected generally with financial questions 
 just as formerly they were with constitutional questions. Public 
 finance has become the central fighting place for social reform. 
 The question of protection has, from the earliest days in this 
 country, been connected with public finance. Police regulation 
 has also been connected with fiscal measures. The license charge 
 for saloons furnishes an illustration. The idea of police power is 
 
 total expenditures, including the national government, states, territories, and local 
 subdivisions, amount to over $1,700,000,000. This would make a per capita 
 expenditure exceeding $20, if the population of the country is estimated at 
 eighty millions. This would mean $100 per family of five; and, on the basis of 
 10 per cent for such a family, would mean an average annual income of $1000. 
 In England the per capita expenditure of the national government alone is over 
 $15.50, and in France over $17. The 10 per cent estimate, then, is clearly an 
 underestimate. 
 
 1 This topic is adequately treated by Professor Charles J. Bullock in his article 
 entitled "The Growth of Federal Expenditures," in the Political Science Quarterly, 
 Vol. XVIII, pp. 97-1 1 1.
 
 558 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 expanding in the United States, and this means expansion of the 
 field of public finance. The discussion of public expenditures 
 reveals, as few other subjects do, the nature of our civiliza- 
 tion. 
 
 Expenditures of Public and Private Economies Contrasted. 
 There is a difference between public and private economies with 
 respect to the equilibrium between income and outgo. Relatively, 
 there is an elasticity of government revenues and an elasticity 
 of government expenditures. This finds expression in the state- 
 ment that public revenues are gauged according to expenditures; 
 whereas, in the private economy, the household expenditures are regu- 
 lated by income. This is a regular rule for normal conditions. 
 It is abnormal when irregularities in public income lead to irregu- 
 larities in expenditures. It has been observed by a critic that 
 this principle of public finance is true in a legal sense, but not in 
 an economic sense. It is said that when public expenditure is 
 decided upon, then we legally determine the income; but, eco- 
 nomically, the expenditures of the state rest upon a foundation 
 as elastic as that of a private person. 1 It is true that in public 
 expenditures there must be a balancing of gain and sacrifice, and 
 that in the case of a particular expenditure it must be weighed 
 over against all other possible expenditures, not only public, but 
 private. The rich state, undoubtedly, will incur expenditures 
 from which a poor but prudent people will probably shrink. On 
 the other hand, a private person is not to be thought of as spend- 
 ing necessarily all his income, even if he gauges his expenditures 
 by income. 
 
 Nevertheless, roughly speaking, the proposition is true on ac- 
 count of the priority of the claims of the state. This has been 
 well brought out by critics of Henry George, who advocated the 
 appropriation of economic rent for public expenditures. Some 
 of Mr. George's followers have replied to the objection that eco- 
 nomic rent might not be sufficient for public expenditures: " Then 
 the state must curtail its expenditures as the private person would 
 do." When we think about it, we find that certain public ex- 
 penditures must be made and must take prior claim. However, 
 1 Cohn, Finanzwissenschaft, S. 184.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 559 
 
 when, as is so often the case in cities, there is an income strictly 
 limited by the tax rate, we frequently have a case like that of 
 a man with a limited and inadequate income. This is an 
 unfortunate situation for cities; but the case of a national 
 government which did not have a prior claim upon wealth for 
 defense would be anomalous. 
 
 Closely connected with what has been said, we find various 
 differences due to the sovereignty of the state and its perpetual 
 life. The state orders a citizen to give up a part of his possessions, 
 and, indeed, frequently fixes prices. And a peculiarity in all 
 states determining prices for property and services is that they 
 must be determined by criteria of fairness, inasmuch as by the 
 very hypothesis competition is wanting wholly or in part. Con- 
 sequently, we find courts and legislatures much occupied with the 
 determination of what is "fair and reasonable." The perpetual 
 life of the state has to be kept in mind m a great variety of ex- 
 penditures. It is the special function of the state to provide for 
 future generations, and this is seen, for example, in forestry and 
 in care for rivers and harbors. 
 
 There is a difference between public and private economies in 
 the means of measuring the utilities resulting from expenditures. 
 It is at once admitted that all expenditures of states and of private 
 persons should, in a large sense, be productive. Waste is every- 
 where an economic wrong, but productive e\penditures mean 
 simply useful expenditures. What the state produces is largely 
 immaterial services, and these have no market price. How can 
 we tell whether they are socially profitable or unprofitable ? They 
 are not worth while if they result in a sacrifice of other expendi- 
 tures which would yield larger satisfactions. It is a special func- 
 tion of the legislative body, in a constitutional state, to decide upon 
 the relative advantages of various possible public expenditures, 
 and to weigh these over against the advantages of private expendi- 
 tures which might have been made if the money permitting the 
 expenditures had been left in private pockets. When a certain 
 sum is taken from me by taxation, it results in a public expendi- 
 ture instead of a private expenditure which might have been 
 made. This is only another way of saying that public expendi-
 
 560 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 tures are largely from income which is derivative. Private indi- 
 viduals secure an income and then yield a part of it for public 
 purposes. These contributions are compulsory. On the other 
 hand, there are economists who look upon the state as a factor in 
 production, and hold that what is paid in taxes is less than what 
 corresponds to the cooperative activity of the state in the mainte- 
 nance of law and order and in other services. The special social 
 significance of public expenditures is that their aim is inclusive, 
 normally and regularly; whereas, normally and regularly, the 
 aims of private expenditures are more or less exclusive. A pub- 
 lic library contrasted with a scholar's private collection of books 
 illustrates this point. 
 
 All these differences are considerable, and they give us perhaps 
 at least one reason why business men are so often a disappoint- 
 ment in an official capacity. The public financier must be gov- 
 erned by the public point of view; and there are many points at 
 which this diverges from the private point of view. The true 
 statesman is one who has the public point of view, and yet is 
 able to avail himself of the knowledge and experience of private 
 business. 
 
 The Proper Proportion between the Total Income of Society and 
 Public Expenditures. We notice actual changes in this propor- 
 tion, and we discover that further changes are advocated, running 
 all the way from the anarchist position, which would abolish gov- 
 ernment and public expenditures, to socialism, which, by making 
 production and distribution public functions, would make public 
 expenditures, broadly construed, nearly equal to the total wealth 
 production. 
 
 An attempt has been made by those who take a less extreme 
 position than either of these to give an estimate of what is a large 
 public expenditure, what a small expenditure, what is desirable, 
 undesirable, or even intolerable. Generally these estimates are 
 made with respect to the maximum expenditure, but we could 
 equally well raise the question with respect to the minimum. 
 One writer speaks of public expenditures of 16 per cent as average, 
 and 25 per cent as excessive. Another regards public expendi- 
 tures which consume 15 per cent of the total annual wealth pro-
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 561 
 
 duction as the upper limit. In our American practice, we very 
 generally attempt to limit the percentage of direct taxes. But 
 the upper limits are based on valuation of property and not on 
 income; while state constitutions very frequently limit state ex- 
 penditures, and also expenditures of cities and other local units. 
 For local purposes in the United States, we have roughly a limit 
 of to 2 per cent of the valuation of property. Total taxation 
 of real property frequently runs in the United States from 
 10 per cent to even 20 per cent of the net profits, and indeed 
 not infrequently goes a great deal beyond that. The truth is, 
 that it is absolutely impossible to give any general answer to the 
 question, "What is the proper proportion between the total in- 
 come of society and public expenditures?" Variations in the 
 wealth of a country have to be considered, and these mean much 
 when the question of additional expenditure is raised. Variations 
 in tax systems and the consequent distribution of the burden of 
 taxation make a wide difference. In times of distress, more can 
 be expended than on ordinary occasions. When the national life 
 of the state is endangered in a war, expenditures will be incurred 
 which would be impossible at any other time, simply because, for 
 any other reason, the people would not submit to the sacrifice 
 involved. 
 
 But there are other points of view which go still deeper. Why 
 do we spend money at all through the state? Obviously to sat- 
 isfy needs. How much we should spend publicly depends upon 
 what needs are satisfied publicly. We have to ask and answer 
 the question, "What position do these needs hold among our 
 needs in general?" "Do they belong to our necessities or super- 
 fluities?" When we consider public expenditures in the broadest 
 terms, we must take into account the amount of production which 
 is carried on by the state employing this term "state" here as 
 elsewhere in its generic sense. If the railways (as in Germany) 
 are state railways, a larger percentage of the expenditures and 
 revenues of the country are public in character than would be the 
 case if they were privately owned and operated. No comparison 
 of expenditures of various countries can have any value if it does 
 not take into account considerations of this kind.
 
 562 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Professor Adolph Wagner 1 lays down this rule, which is helpful 
 in answering the question as to the proper proportion between 
 the income of society and public expenditures for any particular 
 time and place: "The permissible amount of public expendi- 
 tures, both absolutely and relatively considered, will vary directly 
 in proportion to (a) the direct economic value of state activities ; 
 (6) the extent to which it promotes the productive power of all ; 
 (c) the absolutely free social income; 2 (d) the larger the part 
 of the net state receipts coming from the quasi-private acquisi- 
 tion (railways industries in general) of the state and not from 
 taxes." * Fortunately, how much we shall spend presents itself 
 historically, that is, with respect to historical conditions, and 
 has reference to increments or decrements of expenditure. The 
 problem is far easier of solution than it would be otherwise. 
 
 In fact, except as a concrete historical problem, it is impossible 
 to state how great the public expenditures should be. We are 
 now in a position to understand why it is that the nations of the 
 world have not been ruined by expenditures which even a genera- 
 tion ago would have been thought absolutely crushing, and one 
 hundred years ago would have been inconceivable. We satisfy 
 our needs to an ever increasing extent through public agencies. 
 This finds expression in the Law of Increasing Public Expendi- 
 tures, given by the same writer from whom we have just quoted. 
 
 "Comparisons between different countries and different periods 
 show regularly among progressive nations an extension of public 
 activities. This manifests itself extensively and intensively. The 
 state and its subordinate political units continually undertake new 
 functions, and they perform their duties, old and new, better and bet- 
 ter. In this way, that is, through public agency, the needs of the 
 population, to an increasing extent, especially their common needs, 
 are satisfied; and the public services for the satisfaction of needs 
 continually improve in quality. The clear proof of this is given 
 
 1 Finanzwissenchaft, 2te A., Bd. I, S. 65. 
 
 * I.e. beyond and above what is needed for subsistence. 
 
 * This means public ownership of enterprises which are so conducted as to 
 yield profits. All the profits can and indeed must be expended for public pur- 
 poses, whereas, if the industry were private, only a part of the profits could be taken 
 for public purposes.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 563 
 
 statistically in the increased demands made by the state and the sub- 
 ordinate political units." 1 
 
 We have here described what is a part of a still larger move- 
 ment, namely, the socialization of production and the socializa- 
 tion of consumption. It is, however, the socialization of con- 
 sumption which especially confronts us in public expenditures. 
 To an increasing extent what is consumed by the family is pro- 
 duced outside the family. There has been going forward a great 
 process of socialization, and this finds expression in part in public 
 expenditures. An increasing proportion of the needs of the fam- 
 ily are satisfied, not by the private economy, but by the public 
 economy, and satisfied also, as Professor Wagner points out, not 
 in accordance with the principles of private economy, which is 
 service for service, but in accordance with the principles of the 
 public economy, which is a general return for that which is 
 received. 
 
 We have to do with what we may also call socialization of sup- 
 ply. We do not protect ourselves against physical violence, but 
 are protected by the state. We do not educate our own children; 
 they are educated by public agency. The public expenditures 
 are also made to promote art and all the higher interests of life. 
 The services which the federal government renders us in the post 
 office find expression in public expenditures. Public expenditures 
 are giving us more beautiful and more healthful cities, and are 
 satisfying the needs which arise out of the extensive growth of 
 the country, in its expansion geographically and in the size of the 
 population, and also the needs which arise from an intensive 
 growth. 
 
 The significance is partly in increased activity of the state and 
 partly in the incidence of the cost of the services under considera- 
 tion. The poor, who could not themselves have pleasure grounds, 
 enjoy public parks, and these are maintained at public expense. 
 So we may take up one service after another and find that wealth, 
 produced in accordance with the principles of the private economy, 
 is consumed in accordance with the principles of the public econ- 
 
 1 Wagner, Allgemeine Volkswirthschaftslehre, Erster Theil, Grundlegung, Ka. 
 4, 3 Hauptabsch., S. 310, Bd. I, ate A.
 
 564 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 omy, and that is very largely in accordance to needs and capacity 
 for use. The whole public educational system, from the country 
 district school to the modern state university, culminating in re- 
 search and investigation, admirably illustrates this principle. 
 
 The Principle of Economy versus Parsimony in Public Expen- 
 ditures. After a definition of economy in Webster's International 
 Dictionary, we find the following: "Economy, Frugality, Parsi- 
 mony. Economy avoids all waste and extravagance, and applies 
 money to the best advantage; frugality cuts off indulgences, and 
 proceeds on a system of saving. The latter conveys the idea of 
 not using or spending superfluously, and is opposed to lavishness 
 or profusion. Frugality is usually applied to matters of consump- 
 tion, and commonly points to simplicity of manners. Parsimony 
 is frugality carried to an extreme, involving meanness of spirit and 
 a sordid mode of living. Economy is a virtue and parsimony a 
 vice." 
 
 We must have clear ideas as to which course of the three we 
 shall follow, for it is scarcely to be taken for granted that we shall 
 follow the course of extravagance. There is, however, danger of 
 indifference as to the size of public expenditures, and extravagance 
 may result therefrom. While scarcely any one now would delib- 
 erately advocate extravagance so far as the general principle is 
 concerned, extravagance in detail might be advocated; and, in 
 fact, in practice we find both indifference and extravagance. 
 Sometimes the idea that extravagance brings money into circula- 
 tion has found favor, and especially has been used for the justfi- 
 cation of large expenditures by royal courts. The same idea has 
 been used as a justification for luxury. It can, however, find no 
 support in economics. There is danger of extravagance because 
 each one concerned with governmental expenditures feels that 
 what he spends is a relatively small matter, and indeed it is. It 
 is sometimes thoughtlessly overlooked that when many are spend- 
 ing, " small waste " becomes significant, and may be even ruinous. 
 This is a problem which concerns every large business, and it re- 
 quires strict and wise administration to avoids the two extremes : 
 wasteful extravagance and red tape. 
 
 Sectionalism also results in extravagance, and this shows itself
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 565 
 
 badly in the United States at times. Whatever any state can se- 
 cure from the federal Treasury is often looked upon as so much 
 clear gain. This was clearly brought out in the discussions con- 
 cerning the repayment, a few years ago, of the direct tax that 
 has been paid by the states to the federal government. This tax 
 has now been repaid, but many states gave agents large and 
 extravagant sums to work for the refund. Sometimes sectional- 
 ism manifests itself even in cities. In one section of the city 
 there may be vigorous efforts to secure money for itself without 
 due regard for the general interest. 
 
 The peculiar condition of our federal financiering (which is 
 found in the fact that the taxes are kid very largely for other than 
 revenue purposes, and that there is no careful balancing over and 
 against one another of probable revenues and probable expendi- 
 tures) results frequently in a large surplus in the federal Treasury. 
 There is danger of extravagance wherever revenues outrun felt 
 needs. There never has been a time when it would not have been 
 possible to have expended wisely the entire revenues of the federal 
 government; e.g., the telegraph might have been purchased, and 
 educational expenditures might have been increased. But there 
 was no demand for these expenditures strong enough to prevail, 
 and the outlet was found along the lines of least resistance, or, per- 
 haps it ought rather to be said, along the lines of greatest " pull." 
 We may then lay it down as a general law that there is danger of 
 extravagance whenever public revenues outrun felt needs. 
 
 There is a tendency, especially wherever public spirit is not 
 highly developed, to favor parsimony, and to regard that as the 
 best administration which spends least, and the smallest tax as 
 the best tax. This idea was encouraged, particularly by those who 
 looked upon government expenditures as external to the life of the 
 people as if they were expenditures for some outside person. 
 This idea, indeed, may be traced back to monarchical govern- 
 ment and to a time when royal courts consumed a large part of 
 the public revenue. The smallest expenditure means the accom- 
 plishment of the fewest purposes. Parsimony means meanness, 
 and can never be the rule either of public or private financiering. 
 Frugality is the rule when it is a necessity. Economy is the sound
 
 566 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 rule; and this means a broad and liberal policy and a husbanding 
 of resources. The wise citizen judges any particular administra- 
 tion either in the nation or the state, not chiefly by the amount of 
 public expenditures, but by the results of public expenditures, 
 appreciating full well that increasing public expenditures are a 
 normal condition in a sound and healthy society. 
 
 Development of Expenditures and the Historical Order in 
 which they Appear. It is instructive to consider the historical 
 order in which the objects of public expenditure appear. This 
 order throws a strong light upon the evolution of industrial society, 
 and of civilization in general. This is an almost unworked field 
 of investigation, but it is an extremely interesting and important 
 one. This order can be presented here only in the most general 
 terms, and in these terms it is somewhat as follows: expenditures 
 for (i) external security; (2) security within the community; (3) 
 promotion of material interests; (4) benevolence (transferred in 
 part from the Church at the time of the Reformation ; (5) educa- 
 tion in its various phases; (6) labor. In a general way the organi- 
 zation of the departments of the federal government corresponds 
 with this order. In 1789, the Treasury, War, and State depart- 
 ments were organized, also the Department of Justice, Supreme 
 Court, and the Navy Department; the Post Office Department 
 was organized as a distinct department in 1829; the Department 
 of the Interior was organized in 1849; the Department of Labor 
 as a separate department (without representation in the Cabinet) 
 in 1889; the Department of Agriculture as a separate department 
 (with representation in the Cabinet) in 1889; the Department of 
 Commerce and Labor (with representation in the Cabinet) in 
 1903. The modern nation has been spending an increasing pro- 
 portion of its resources for education. We use nation in the gen- 
 eral sense here, including all the subdivisions of the nation. We 
 find a rapidly increasing item in the budget of the modern munici- 
 pality for public libraries, in which line of expenditure the United 
 States is leading the world. Lately, in the modern budget, we 
 find expenditures which are distinctively for the promotion of the 
 interests of labor. 
 
 Most interesting is it to observe, within the last few years, an
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 567 
 
 expenditure in the national budgets for international agreements 
 and arrangements to promote the interests of labor. In 1900, the 
 International Association for Labor Legislation was formed, and 
 its permanent Bureau was established at Basle, Switzerland, in 
 1901. As the competition of labor and capital was international, 
 it had, in the opinion of many careful observers, become necessary 
 to safeguard the interests of labor by international agreements. 
 Consequently, we find that this international association receives 
 subsidies from most European governments, and a small one from 
 the United States through our federal Bureau of Labor. And, 
 in 1905, as we have already seen, an international treaty was en- 
 tered into by Italy and France for the advancement of the inter- 
 ests of labor and for mutual protection of employers. Small 
 indeed are these items, but they are significant as beginnings. 
 
 We must, however, analyze the public expenditures of the vari- 
 ous departments more carefully to understand fully the order of 
 development in the objects of public expenditures. The whole 
 expenditure of the Department of Agriculture is an expenditure 
 to promote material well-being, and this has become one of the 
 great departments in modern government. The Department of 
 the Interior is also largely concerned with expenditures to pro- 
 mote the general material welfare. We have in the Department 
 of Agriculture such items as forestry, food adulteration, botany, 
 seed tests, pomology, entomology, agricultural soils, irrigation 
 investigations, and road inquiry. 
 
 We cannot lay down any hard and fast line between public and 
 private expenditures, because there is a perpetual shifting from 
 the satisfaction of wants privately to the satisfaction of wants 
 publicly, and sometimes even, though less frequently, the reverse 
 process. The railways of Prussia were once private, and their re- 
 ceipts and expenditures had little to do with the Prussian budget. 
 Now the receipts are public receipts, and their expenditures 
 are public expenditures. The addition to the budget, however, 
 means necessarily no additional burden resting on the people. 
 Indeed, if the people are well served and served for a lower price 
 than formerly, with less relative cost of operation, the burdens of 
 the people have been lightened, and this is what is generally
 
 568 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 claimed in Prussia. Let us take the case of a city in which water- 
 ing the streets is a private matter paid for by private subscription. 
 The expenditure becomes a public expenditure when the city 
 takes upon itself this function, but if the public expenditure is no 
 greater than the private expenditure, there is no additional burden. 
 If the service is better performed, and the total burden more 
 fairly distributed by taxation than by private subscription, as 
 sometimes, at least, happens, there is a positive gain. The in- 
 creased density of population has been mentioned as a cause of 
 increased public expenditures. A suburb without any municipal 
 organization may maintain electric lights in the streets by pri- 
 vate subscription. The expenditure appears in no public budget. 
 This suburb secures some kind of a municipal organization, and 
 that which was a private expenditure becomes a public expendi- 
 ture. Again, however, there is no increased burden resting upon 
 the people; their wants are satisfied through a different channel. 
 When we compare modern times with ancient times, we find 
 that an increasing proportion of the public expenditures are in- 
 curred for objects which directly benefit the people, and relatively 
 a decreasing amount for objects in which they have comparatively 
 little concern. This finds most striking exemplification in a com- 
 parison of the budget of France in 1789 1 with the budgets of 1906 
 and 1907, which we take simply as typical modern budgets. 2 
 
 EXPENSES 1 789 
 
 LlVRES ' 
 
 Cost of collection and reimbursements (does not include 
 cost of collecting taxes farmed out) 
 
 71,478,000 
 
 Consolidated debt included portion made up of annuities 
 Interest etc on remaining portion of debt 
 
 162,486,000 
 
 80.? 27 OOO 
 
 Pensions . 
 
 20,560,000 
 
 Royal family and princes 
 
 33.2,10.000 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 337,201,000 
 
 
 
 1 A livre is slightly less than a franc say 2 per cent. 
 
 1 Necker*s "Budget," May, 1789, rearranged by the author of the article in the 
 Dictionnaire des Finances. * On page 570.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 
 
 "This formed the total deduction before provision could be 
 made for general service of the government," in which we have 
 the following items : 
 
 EXPENSES 1789 (Continued) 
 
 LIVRES 
 
 War 
 
 
 Marine and colonies 
 
 
 Foreign affairs 
 
 
 Justice 
 
 
 Interior 
 
 
 Financial administration 
 
 
 Public works, agriculture, and commerce 
 
 
 Public instruction and fine arts 
 
 I 227 OOO 
 
 Public worship (" cultes ") 
 
 2 188 ooo 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 I&A 6c? ooo 
 
 Brought forward 
 
 lit 2O I OOO 
 
 
 
 Grand total 
 
 C2I ClAA OOO 
 
 
 
 It will be observed, in comparing these budgets, that the French 
 court consumed a very large proportion of the expenditures of 
 1789; and that of what remained a very large proportion was 
 consumed by the public debt, the army and navy; and that for 
 education and the promotion of general welfare the expenditure 
 was relatively insignificant. A study of the table on next page 
 reveals one of the reasons why_it is that France is able to endure 
 so large a public expenditure. Wants are thereby satisfied, and 
 what is expended returns to the people in services. 
 
 The view here presented of public expenditures is undoubtedly 
 one which is reassuring. The impression must not be gathered 
 from this that there is no need for care and watchfulness. As 
 public expenditures increase, it becomes of more and more im- 
 portance to secure wise and prudent administration of all our 
 resources. Wastefulness becomes more serious than ever before, 
 and the benefits from excellence in administration increase cor- 
 respondingly. Without pronouncing any opinion upon what is
 
 57 
 
 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 called imperialism, we may also say that the enormous increase in 
 expenditures, in one way or another connected with war, which 
 we have seen during the past few years, cannot be viewed without 
 misgiving. Even the most optimistic Englishman cannot regard 
 with complacency a national administration approaching in its 
 expenditures 150,000,000 sterling, when over one third is for the 
 
 BRANCHES OF EXPENDITURES 
 
 1907 
 
 Francs 
 
 1906 
 
 Francs 
 
 Finance : public debt 
 
 1, 277, c 28, 064. 
 
 1.232 411 OO2 
 
 President, Chamber, Senate .... 
 Other services 
 
 19.337.500 
 
 7O4,67 i ;,';2C 
 
 13,942,500 
 2O8,IOO 361 
 
 Justice 
 
 78 7IO 2CO 
 
 77 ,177 6OO 
 
 Foreign affairs 
 
 19 I IO OOO 
 
 17 68 C 760 
 
 Interior 
 
 104 066 146 
 
 80 117 177 
 
 War 
 
 770,086,1 7Q 
 
 718,690,882 
 
 ^Marine 
 
 3121 69 8 1 o 
 
 72C 08 1 O4I 
 
 Instruction 
 
 261.267 ^46 
 
 251 240 010 
 
 Fine arts 
 
 17 d6j. C24 
 
 17 AA& I4O 
 
 Worship 
 
 CO7 I 7O 
 
 C *O T 7O 
 
 Commerce and industry 
 
 C6,4QO,7O7 
 
 1:6,276,271 
 
 Labor, etc 
 
 12 C4O OIO 
 
 
 Posts and telegraphs 
 
 2OO O7O 08? 
 
 267 42O,4IO 
 
 Colonies 
 
 TOO 477 77O 
 
 TIO.4IC.IOO 
 
 Agriculture 
 
 A.Z.2IZ 146 
 
 4 <J, 0^7.684 
 
 Public works 
 
 229,134,470 
 
 228,374,599 
 
 Total 
 
 3. 83.7..82^,7oc 
 
 3.700.102.06? 
 
 
 
 
 army and navy. Even if there is no danger of the bankruptcy 
 of any great modern nation, the thought must at least occur to 
 one that it is a pity that, with so many public needs unsatisfied, 
 with such large possibilities in the way of improvement of educa- 
 tion and our general environment, such enormous and almost 
 incomprehensible aggregates of wealth should be annually ex- 
 pended for warlike purposes. 
 
 Development of Public Expenditures with respect to Regu- 
 larity and Irregularity. Public expenditures are regular and 
 irregular, or ordinary and extraordinary, with respect to their 
 occurrence. Whether the expenditures are regular or not depends
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 571 
 
 upon the nature of the goods and services for which they are in- 
 curred. A large force must be employed in the army and navy 
 and civil service; and regular expenditures must be made for 
 these branches of the public service. On the other hand, there 
 are great monumental works like the construction of a capitol 
 for which the expenditure is irregular in character. War, famine, 
 and pestilence occasion irregular expenditures. It is to be no- 
 ticed, however, that in any scientific arrangement regular expendi- 
 tures increase and irregular expenditures decrease. This is par- 
 ticularly the case in a large country, and especially so when long 
 periods of time are taken into account. It is an end to be striven 
 for in the interest of orderly finance. In India there is a regular 
 famine fund to make provision for the recurring famines, so that 
 even expenditure of this kind takes on the character of regularity. 
 The longer the period of time and the larger and richer the coun- 
 try, the greater the possibilities of establishing regularity, inas- 
 much as chance elements decrease under these circumstances. 
 The construction of a post office building in one city is an unusual 
 event, but, when the United States as a whole is taken into account, 
 it is quite possible to provide regularly for post office buildings. 
 
 It is further to be noticed that preventive measures rather than 
 relief measures increase regular expenditures. This is one argu- 
 ment in favor of constant preparation for war. The war expendi- 
 tures are smaller and less disturbing when they come. It need 
 not be remarked that this financial advantage may be secured at 
 a loss otherwise. Furthermore, there is a certain conflict of 
 interests between administration and legislation. Those who are 
 administratively responsible for expenditures prefer to have budg- 
 ets voted for long periods, as in this way they can accomplish 
 most with a given sum. On the other hand, a legislative branch 
 of government desires that budgets should be voted for short 
 periods for the sake of stricter control. 
 
 It is also to be noticed that the constitutional provisions against 
 debts in the states of the American Union promote regular expendi- 
 tures. Where loans are not possible, it is frequently necessary to 
 spread expenditures over long periods in order that the burden 
 may not be too great at any one time. It is in this way that in the
 
 572 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 state of Wisconsin, for example, the Historical Library Building 
 was built; and many of the buildings of the State University have 
 been constructed under like conditions. It is in this way that the 
 new Capitol is being built. Certain sums are appropriated each 
 year for a series of years. 1 
 
 Terms used in Public Expenditures. The terminology of public finance, 
 and in particular of public expenditures, has occupied a great deal of attention 
 on the part of economists, and receives elaborate treatment in the Census 
 Report, 1907, on Wealth, Debt, and Taxation. It is here possible to point out 
 simply a few distinctions and to define a very few terms; but in a more 
 elaborate and technical treatise on public finance it would be necessary to 
 give a great deal of attention to this topic. 
 
 Instead of the term " public expenditures," we sometimes have the term 
 "financial needs." This is employed particularly by German writers, 
 who, however, employ it interchangeably with expenditures. The two terms 
 represent two approaches to the same subject. Educational needs, treated 
 from the financial standpoint, become expenditures for education. "Ex- 
 penditures" seems to be the more natural term. 
 
 We must distinguish between expenditures in the narrow sense and invest- 
 ments. In the broad, general sense, all governmental outlays would be 
 designated as expenditures. In a narrow sense we use "expenditures" 
 for those outlays which are not expected to yield a direct, material return, 
 and "investments" for those outlays which are expected to yield such a 
 return. An investment would mean an outlay of capital rendering a direct 
 income equal to current interest. If the return is less than current interest, 
 it partakes of the nature of expenditures in the narrow sense of the term. 
 Money expended in improving and extending the state railways of Germany, 
 for example, would be regarded as investment. Money expended on the 
 streets of cities are expenditures. This distinction is one of increasing sig- 
 nificance because governments are extending their functions in the industrial 
 field. In all sound public financiering, especially in all action concerning 
 public debts, the distinction must be made between an outlay of capital which 
 will yield a return at least equal to the current rate of interest and those out- 
 lays which yield their return in direct and immediate satisfactions, but do not 
 make any direct and immediate provision for interest payments and final 
 amortization. 
 
 1 The authors hope by taking concrete illustrations from their own environment 
 that they will accomplish two purposes: (i) that the text will be rendered more 
 real and less abstract, and (2) that their readers will be encouraged to seek illustra- 
 tions from their environment. One aim which is constantly kept in mind is the 
 importance of cultivating the power of observing and reflecting upon economic 
 phenomena.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 573 
 
 It is generally conceded that narrow debt limits should not be applied in 
 the case of cities to investments. 
 
 The census volume just referred to makes a further distinction between 
 investments and outlays as follows: "Under investments are included all 
 transactions of national, state, and municipal governments connected with 
 the purchase, sale, or possession of real property or securities held exclusively 
 for investment purposes, and the loan of public money to individuals, cor- 
 porations, or other civil divisions. Such transactions are of two classes : 
 first, those of the sinking, investment, and public trust funds in which or 
 through which the nation, state, or municipality invests money for the sole 
 purpose of deriving interest, rent, or other income therefrom; second, the 
 transactions of a more temporary character by which the national, state, or 
 municipal government receives interest on current cash deposits and on 
 deferred payments of taxes and special assessments." * 
 
 "Outlays 'Outlays' are the costs, paid or payable, incurred by nations, 
 states, and municipalities in the purchase of lands, in the purchase or con- 
 struction of buildings and other structures, and in the equipment, improve- 
 ment, and additions to public works which are more or less permanent 
 in character, and which are used by the nations, states, and municipalities 
 in the exercise of their general functions or in connection with the business 
 undertakings conducted by them. Governmental outlays partake of the na- 
 ture both of commercial expenses and of commercial capital outlays. Like 
 commercial outlays, they are to secure more or less permanent acquisitions; 
 but unlike them, they do not secure property applicable under any ordinary 
 condition for meeting liabilities. Further, they are always a legal charge 
 against revenue, while capital expenditures in commercial undertakings 
 are always recorded in the accounts with capital." J 
 
 A further important distinction is that between expenditures for works of 
 a permanent character and those of a more temporary character. The prod- 
 ucts of expenditures of a permanent character are those which keep on 
 yielding utilities indefinitely a public park, for example. The expenditure 
 for utilities of a temporary character are those which must be perpetually 
 renewed, like an annual expenditure for the maintenance of public parks. 
 This is a distinction which must always be observed in sound public finance. 
 
 Classification of Public Expenditures. Many principles of classification 
 have been adopted. An important one is that made with respect to political 
 units: 
 
 I. Central. 
 II. Intermediate. 
 III. Local units. 
 
 This classification can be extended indefinitely, but it gives us the three 
 main classes of units. In our country the central would be the federal, the 
 intermediate would be the separate states, and the others, the local. An 
 
 1 P- 95 6 - * P- 954-
 
 574 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 examination of expenditures with respect to these units throws a good deal 
 of light upon our general political evolution. It especially helps us to de- 
 termine whether or not there is a tendency in the direction of centralization, 
 although expenditures alone are not conclusive. Sometimes fear has been 
 expressed lest the central governments should expand at the expense of the 
 local governments. It is thought by some that we are living in a period of 
 centralization. The statistics of public expenditures do not bear this out, 
 as local expenditures seem to be increasing more rapidly than those of central 
 governments. There may be some ground to apprehend that in the United 
 States the cities and federal government are increasing in importance more 
 rapidly than our commonwealths. The states which make up the Union 
 have lost somewhat in relative significance, if we may judge from the com- 
 parison of public expenditures of the various political units. 1 There appears 
 to^be, however,jsome ground for thinking that the states are again becoming 
 of greater importance in our general structure of government. We find, 
 for example, that the expenditures of the state of New York have increased 
 from not quite $10,000,000 in 1881 to nearly $22,000,000 in 1902. This is 
 a budget which would seem to indicate activity, although, to be sure, far less 
 than the budget of New York City. Our Western states are developing 
 remarkable educational systems, reaching from the common school to the 
 university, and some of our states are developing forest property, and a 
 department of forestry. These are, perhaps, ample illustrations of the 
 growing significance of the state. But we must await future developments 
 in order to ascertain the extent of the movement. 
 
 The following is a very simple classification made with respect to objects 
 for expenditure : 
 
 I. Expenditures for security. 
 II. Expenditures for the poor and unfortunate. 
 III. Expenditures for education. 
 IV. Expenditures for commerce, diplomacy, and government. 
 
 The following is a more extensive classification : 3 
 I. Head of the state. 
 II. Legislative bodies. 
 
 III. Public administration, including central departments. 
 
 IV. Army and navy. 
 
 I. Head of the state emperor, kings, grand dukes, etc., Germany. 
 Presidents and governors representing the sovereignty of the state. 
 
 1 It must again be emphasized that expenditures alone are not sufficient evidence 
 to enable us to speak positively on this point. In general, however, there is a 
 correspondence between the amount of public money expended by a political 
 unit and its social significance. 
 
 'This is taken largely from Cossa's Taxation: Its Principles and Methods, 
 Part II, Chap. Ill, Classification of Public Expenditures.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 575 
 
 II. Legislative bodies Congress, legislatures, county boards, county 
 
 councils, municipal councils. 
 III. Public administration central, intermediate, local. 
 
 A. Financial administration. 
 
 1. Treasury. 
 
 2. Public domain (regalia) fiscal monopolies, public business. 
 
 Further subdivision possible. 
 
 3. Administration (especially collection) of taxes. 
 
 4. Public debts. (Sinking funds, etc.) 
 
 B. Administration of foreign affairs diplomacy, consulates, etc. 
 
 C. Administration of the interior. 
 
 1. Internal security. 
 Courts. 
 
 U.S. marshals. 
 
 Constables. 
 
 Police, etc. 
 
 Repression and prevention. 
 
 2. The administration designed to promote general public welfare. 
 
 a. Intellectual and moral welfare. 
 
 Education in its various phases. Statistical bureaus, etc. 
 
 b. Physical welfare. 
 
 (a) General economic well-being: economic welfare in 
 
 general the promotion of manufactures, agricul- 
 ture, and commerce. Weather bureau. 
 
 (b) Life saving in general. Public health. Sanitary ad- 
 
 ministration. 
 
 (c) Charitable and provident institutions. 
 
 (d) Public works, including model institutions, etc., such as 
 
 farms. 
 (c) The promotion of the interests of labor. Here there is 
 
 overlapping, for the labor bureau is educational also. 
 (/) Pleasure, recreation, and miscellaneous. 
 
 IV. Army and navy. 
 
 Regular army and navy militia. 
 
 The student, and even the general reader, will find it especially instructive 
 to study the financial reports of the federal government and of our states and 
 cities, and arrange the items of expenditures under these various heads. 
 If access can be had to reports covering a considerable number of years and 
 different countries, it will be found that an examination of them will throw an 
 immense amount of light upon the nature of modern civilization and its 
 direction. 
 
 It is also instructive to compare expenditures on account of the head of the 
 state in various countries, and particularly to contrast monarchical and
 
 576 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 republican countries. It is important to discover great historical tendencies, 
 and to contrast different periods of time, especially as regards monarchical 
 expenditures. It is beyond all question that relatively, in the civilized world, 
 this is an item of declining importance. At the present time, the king of a 
 great country like Prussia or England supports a magnificence of state which 
 is altogether out of keeping with the ideas of a democracy or a republic. 
 Four or five millions of dollars per annum for a modern monarch is not a 
 large expenditure. On the other hand, in contrast, the expenditures of the 
 President of the United States (including those connected with the executive 
 mansion, contingent expenses of all sorts, and presidential clerks) amount 
 roughly to $150,000. However, as regards the expenditures of a modern 
 monarch (like the German Emperor William II), a detailed examination 
 shows that custom and tradition, as well as the will of the monarch, cause 
 a large part of his income to go for public purposes, and that his wealth has 
 been largely socialized. The king is no longer the typical rich man. 
 
 On the other hand, the expenditures on account of the American Congress 
 are unprecedented in amount among the expenditures incurred on account 
 of legislative bodies. The world has never seen anything of the kind be- 
 fore, and nothing parallel to it can be found in any other country. Among 
 other things, this goes to indicate, as contrasted with Germany, the great 
 importance of the legislative body which is supposed to represent the people 
 directly and immediately and to carry out their will. In aristocratic countries 
 the legislative office is sometimes an unpaid office. This is the case in 
 British and German parliaments, the idea being to favor wealth and to 
 counteract democratic tendencies an aim not accomplished at present. 
 A democracy, however, is more likely to insist upon a legislative office being 
 a paid office ; and, in some of the German states, although the payment is 
 small, its acceptance is compulsory for the members of the legislative 
 bodies. 
 
 Expenditures incurred in the administration of foreign affairs are of in- 
 creasing importance on account of growing economic internationalism. We 
 would here have two main classes; namely, expenditures on account of 
 diplomacy, those representing the purely political side of government, and 
 expenditures on account of the consular service, representing the business 
 interests of the country. Boundaries and surveys are expenses which would 
 come under this general heading. 
 
 With regard to the administration of foreign affairs, any one nation is 
 limited in what it can do by international customs. We Americans, for 
 example, cannot force our ideas on other nations. Certain standards of 
 dignity and propriety have been established with respect to the mode of life 
 for diplomats, and, if we depart from these, we do so at a loss which every 
 diplomat in the service of the United States keenly feels. The most that we 
 can do is to exercise pressure in what we believe to be the right direction, and 
 that is the direction of democratic simplicity.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 577 
 
 When we examine expenses incurred in the administration of justice, we 
 notice a large increase with the growth of democracy. In earlier times in 
 countries like England and Germany, the administration of justice was to a 
 greater or less extent "patrimonial," being connected with certain estates. 
 The duty of administering justice went with the great estate or manor and 
 involved little expense. As people take things into their own hands they 
 must pay their own expenses. Democracy, in its progress, means large 
 public expenditures. 
 
 The new humanitarianism of the age, which, in a way, is one expression of 
 democracy, involves large expenditures, as seen in education, modern re- 
 formatories, etc. But it is believed by the advocates of humanitarianism and 
 democracy that these expenditures are worth while. 
 
 It is when we come to expenses incurred in the promotion of the general 
 welfare that we see the most remarkable and edifying phenomena that greet 
 us in the treatment of public expenditures. This has been seen in the 
 data already given, and will become increasingly manifest as the student car- 
 ries on his statistical studies in this field. 1 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. Define public finance. Why should it be regarded as a part of eco- 
 nomics? Can you give any reasons why it should be regarded as a sepa- 
 rate science ? 
 
 2. Can we spare money for taxes only when we have an income affording 
 a surplus over and above necessities ? If the money paid for taxes is used to 
 provide us with necessities, is there any good ground for the doctrine that an 
 income sufficient to afford a minimum of subsistence should be exempted 
 from taxation in the case of an income tax ? 
 
 3. What various meanings do you ascribe to the enormous increase in 
 public expenditures during the nineteenth century ? 
 
 4. What would be the consequences if the government of the state in 
 which you live should strive for the largest possible amount of revenue, and 
 then govern its expenditures so as to consume the entire state income ? 
 
 5. Discuss the differences between public expenditures and the expendi- 
 tures of a private household. Would you regard it wise on your part to 
 make any expenditures with the idea that a benefit to some one would accrue 
 one hundred years later ? fifty years later ? twenty years later ? 
 
 6. What considerations must govern us when we attempt to answer the 
 question, " What is the proper proportion between public expenditures and 
 the total income of society?" 
 
 7. Discuss Wagner's rule. Is the fact that public ownership increases 
 the permissible proportion of social income that may be used for public 
 
 1 For statistical matter bearing upon the subject-matter of this chapter, see 
 Appendix A. 
 
 2P
 
 578 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 purposes an argument for public ownership of railways ? If so, why ? If not, 
 why not ? 
 
 8. Discuss Wagner's law of increasing public expenditures and show its 
 significance. 
 
 9. Discuss economy, parsimony, frugality, extravagance in public ex- 
 penditures, and give as full illustrations of each as you are able (a) from your 
 own observation, (6) from your reading and conversation and correspondence 
 with others, public officials included. Make this the subject of a topic for a 
 class report. 
 
 10. Discuss the historical order in which items of expenditure appear in 
 national, state, and local governments. Give illustrations from the state and 
 from the local political unit in which you live. Give any illustration which 
 may occur to you of taxation which lightens the burdens of the taxpayer. 
 Does it afford you satisfaction when you buy postage stamps to know that the 
 money paid flows into the public treasury, and not into the treasury of a 
 private corporation? 
 
 11. If you were permanent Secetary of War, would you desire to know for 
 a long number of years in advance the yearly sums that could be expended 
 on the army ? Could you thus make the same amount of money accomplish 
 more than if dependent upon annual grants uncertain in amount? What 
 would be your view as a member of Congress? Is a state university to be 
 controlled in its expenditures by the legislature as rigidly as Congress should 
 control the administration of the army? If so, why? If not, why not? 
 Would you make any distinction in this respect between the army and the 
 navy? 
 
 12. Point out the different kinds of public expenditures and distinctions 
 between expenditures and investments, and show their significance. If 
 public parks, like publicly owned railways, yield permanently services to 
 society, why should different rules of financiering apply to them ? 
 
 13. Present such statistics as you may be able to gather showing relatively 
 and for as long a time as possible the increases in public expenditures in the 
 federal government, in your own state, and in your own local political unit 
 (city, county, town, etc.), and give all the evidence that you can secure showing 
 the significance of the movement. 
 
 14. Show the various ways in which the increasing degree of self-govern- 
 ment and the growing altruism of the age bring about an expansion of public 
 expenditures. Is it worth while? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 Government publications generally. 
 
 As illustrative particularly of the expansion of government expenditures and 
 
 public work, the Year Book of the Department of Agriculture. 
 For growth of militarism, take publications of the Department of War and 
 
 publications of similar departments in other countries.
 
 PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 579 
 
 For general statistical data, Martin's Statesman's Year Book is as reliable as 
 anything in English. For our own country, see Finance Reports of the 
 Secretary of the Treasury and census volumes, especially the volume on 
 Wealth, Debt, and Taxation. For making a broad survey of the federal 
 expenditures of the United States, perhaps no single publication is more 
 useful than the annual " Letter from the Secretary of the Treasury trans- 
 mitting estimates of appropriations."
 
 CHAPTER XXXIII 
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES FROM LOANS AND GOVERNMENT 
 OWNERSHIP 
 
 Classification. Having decided what expenditures it is pos- 
 sible or desirable to make, the question next arises how the neces- 
 sary revenues may be raised. Differing classifications of public 
 revenue have been almost as numerous as the writers who have 
 made them. Without entering into a discussion of the reason for 
 such differences, we may present at once a classification which is 
 in general harmony with the usual treatment of the subject. It 
 should be distinctly understood that the figures accompanying the 
 classification are only approximately correct, as it is still impossible 
 to fit public accounts, particularly those of the national govern- 
 ment, to that classification which long study has shown to be most 
 serviceable to the economic student. 
 
 The figures in Table I are derived from the Census Report entitled 
 Wealth, Debt, and Taxation (Part II, Table 2, and Part IV, Tables 2, 
 12, 13, 14, 15, 18), and from Census Bulletins 20, 45, and 50. The figures 
 refer, for the most part, to the fiscal year ending June 30, 1903, but this is 
 not true in all cases. In addition to the "receipts from revenues," as defined 
 by the Census Bureau (Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, Part IV, Table i), 
 Table I includes $119,722,845 for public debt and $11,391,791 for revenue 
 from public domains, not included in the census totals. The $119,722,845 
 represents the increase of public debt in one year, i.e. the difference between 
 the receipts on account of the public debt and the payments on the same 
 account, but it takes no cognizance of the increase of cash and other assets 
 available for the payment of the debt. In arriving at the total, $4,000,000 
 has been allowed for the increase in the debt of the minor civil divisions 
 other than counties and cities having more than eight thousand inhabitants. 
 The $11,391,791 represents an estimate of the receipts from the sale of 
 public lands by the national and state governments. This item is classed 
 by the census statisticians with the nominal, or, in their designation, the 
 "temporary " receipts, on the ground that when real estate is sold, the revenue 
 is offset by a corresponding decrease in the capital assets or the aggregate
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 
 
 H/fey 
 
 S s 8 
 3 
 
 H < 
 
 ^ w" 
 
 c 
 
 3 
 
 fc 
 
 
 CO W'CNONO^OTf^oOw O 
 fx OO ^ 00 *O n T 1 w O w O* O 
 
 
 <o 
 
 
 O* ^ O ^ M ^O W N W CO O 
 2 oo -i - t^ r^ o 
 
 <7> M 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 00 
 
 
 O MM^MMOPtttVOOk V) 
 
 ir>^fobfO'OMOOOtH ro 
 
 V 
 
 3 
 
 JJ. 
 
 
 O M^fOrooO^OO* *^- O 1 ^ O^ ^O 
 iy> M Q\ O O OO *-" t^* w O fr > *** 
 
 t> M M IO O ^O Ov t"* O M ^ ^ 
 
 
 o\ 
 
 M 
 M 
 
 
 O^ ^o *O V O t^- ^H o^ O ^> O ^ O^ 
 
 OO M \o M IH 10 ^ ro OO t^- O 
 
 ; M " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 : ::::: : : : a 
 
 
 
 
 2 r 
 
 
 
 
 o. : ^c, 
 
 
 
 
 . u , . w 
 
 
 
 
 ; ; ; ; ; ;i ; ; ;| 
 
 
 
 u 
 
 o 
 
 c 
 
 * IT 
 
 o 3 
 
 1 8 
 
 CX, * u co o> 
 
 s i i l 
 
 :{j 8 3 
 
 M o- 
 I 8 S i v 
 
 -M .S <C to "S 4J 
 
 C td to o > b 
 
 gills. -2 
 
 E -S -g S 
 
 w vU o <n w C 
 
 
 evenues 
 
 ~ 
 
 o it* 
 
 * o 
 "o t> 
 
 Si 
 
 s - 
 
 |l 
 
 en 2 
 
 C C 
 
 s 8 
 
 a. s 3 s c < **! 
 e^^.si g 
 
 ^181-S | s 
 
 *-~ * S | =3 
 M ySSSg 3 a 
 
 g^333 - 
 oS^CCCu 41 8 S 
 
 v e^uucix-icnG^ . 
 a S_,>>>_,SjbT3 J 
 
 | ll^^^l^c^E^ 
 G ^ 'C . . . 'C . . . tj "O 
 
 
 A. Temporary R 
 
 3 3 
 
 3 
 
 ~ - 
 
 H-t 
 
 ft^ H O ?J ^O vo 1> Q *O v\i rt 
 ^ Q 3 rt 
 
 7; 3 OO 1- 
 
 i 8P M ci i <3 
 
 3 K A 
 
 5 . 
 
 i ~ 
 
 05
 
 582 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 value of the fixed possessions of the government. The justice of this treat- 
 ment is plain in the case of municipal buildings and other real estate forming 
 part of the fixed plant of the municipality, but it is not so clear in the case of 
 the public lands of the state and national governments which for the most 
 part yield no revenue and resemble the merchandise or stock rather than the 
 capital or plant of the private business. In the figures given in the table, 
 ineradicable duplications to the amount of about $70,000,000 occur, although 
 most of the common duplications such as transfers and refunding operations 
 generally have been eliminated by the excellent classification employed in 
 the Census Report. It should be added, also, that in practice it is im- 
 possible to differentiate clearly among taxes, fees, revenues from public 
 domains, and revenues from public industries, and that the assignment of 
 the detailed items to these classes is in some cases quite arbitrary. 
 
 Temporary Revenues and Public Debts. The modern State 
 follows a policy of deficit financiering. The great and increasing 
 expenditures, which have been described in the preceding chapter, 
 entail burdens too heavy to be borne, at least in the first instance, 
 by taxation alone, and recourse must constantly be had to the 
 public credit. One year with another, about one fourth of the 
 annual revenue of England is used in the payment of debt or 
 interest upon debt; and as was shown in the French budgets for 
 1906 and 1907, given on page 570, almost one third of the total 
 expenditures of France is devoted to the same purpose. 
 
 In the last half of the nineteenth century, the aggregate public 
 debt of the civilized world increased enormously. According to 
 the best estimates, the indebtedness of the national governments of 
 the world, which amounted to $7,627,692,215 in 1848, had risen 
 to $27,524,976,915 in 1890, and since that time it has probably 
 increased. Figures showing the total and per capita debt of all 
 governmental divisions of this country are given in Table II. 
 From this statement it appears that between 1890 and 1902 the 
 aggregate public debt of this country increased over $800,000,000, 
 the greater part of the increase being ascribable to the astonish- 
 ing growth of municipal and local indebtedness, which increased 
 nearly 90 per cent in the interval. It is true that the total 
 public debt has diminished since 1880, that the per capita debt 
 has fallen from $82.99 m ^7 to $35-5 m 1902, and that accord- 
 ing to Census estimates of national wealth (not very trustworthy), 
 the public debt covered only $2.85 of each one hundred dollars of
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 
 
 583 
 
 national wealth in 1902, as against $3.06 in 1890, $6.97 in 1880, 
 and $10.64 in 1870. But this diminution of the aggregate debt 
 is due to the extraordinary progress which our tariff surpluses have 
 enabled us to make in reducing the debt contracted during the 
 Civil War; and the normal movement in the long run is probably 
 toward an increase of the public debt, at least absolutely and per 
 capita, if not in proportion to the national wealth. 1 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 PUBLIC DEBT OF THE UNITED STATES 
 Net Debt Outstanding 
 
 TOTAL IN MILLIONS OF DOLLARS 
 
 PER CAPITA 
 
 
 1902 
 
 1890 
 
 1880 
 
 1870 
 
 1902 
 
 1890 
 
 1880 
 
 1870 
 
 Total 
 
 $2790 
 925 
 
 235 
 197 
 
 1387 
 46 
 
 $1989 
 852 
 
 211 
 
 MS 
 
 744 
 37 
 
 $343 
 1919 
 
 275 
 124 
 
 707 1 
 i8f 
 
 $3200 
 2 33 * 
 
 353 
 188 
 
 328 
 
 $35 -5 
 11.77 
 
 2.99 
 2.50 
 
 17-65 
 o-59 
 
 $31.76 
 13.60 
 
 3-37 
 2.32 
 
 11.88 
 o-59 
 
 $60.66 
 38-27 
 
 5-48 
 2-47 
 
 14.09! 
 o-35 J 
 
 $82.99 
 60.46 
 
 9-i5 
 4-87 
 
 8.51 
 
 National gov't. . 
 States and terri- 
 tories 
 
 Counties 
 
 Cities, villages, 
 etc 
 
 School districts . 
 
 The great increase of public debts is due principally to two causes, 
 wars and public works. The former are misfortunes, losses, how- 
 ever the result is expressed. The loss comes, not in contracting a 
 debt, but in spending and destroying the property consumed by 
 war. This loss cannot be postponed by a debt. It comes out of 
 wealth existing at the time, no matter what arrangement is made. 
 In former times each man bore the loss as it happened to fall on 
 him. The modern method differs in just this, that the loss is 
 transferred to the whole public. This, again, may be done in two 
 ways. A tax may be levied at the time sufficient to pay all 
 
 1 According to Census estimates, the per capita debt of the United Kingdom 
 in 1904-1905 was 3.93, that of France 4.86, and that of Italy 2.25 times as great 
 as the per capita debt of the United States in 1902, while that of Sweden was a 
 trifle less than the per capita debt of the United States.
 
 584 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 expenses, or a debt may be incurred and the necessary taxation 
 spread over a longer period of time. In practice the latter proves 
 far the best, for at least a part of the expenses. It gives capital 
 time to adjust itself to the extraordinary demands. A war debt 
 is, therefore, not a misfortune, though it stands for a previous 
 misfortune war. 
 
 The case is clearer when we consider debts contracted for public 
 works. Under this head we include primarily productive enter- 
 prises like railways, canals, forests, gas works. These, when pur- 
 chased or constructed by the government, are the occasion of 
 debts, sometimes enormous in amount. It might seem possible 
 to pay for them by immediate and heavy taxation, since no more 
 is taken out of the people than when the money is borrowed. But 
 the national wealth is not like an ocean, alike in all its parts and 
 instantly filling up where water is dipped out. It makes all the 
 difference in the world where you dip. Here are men who have 
 capital invested in a productive business; here are others who have 
 capital lying idle. The State decides to make a public investment, 
 and calls for capital. If it collects it by an immediate and heavy 
 tax, the first class have a part of their employed capital withdrawn, 
 and their business is crippled or ruined. The others have some 
 of their capital withdrawn, but the most still lies idle. The best 
 that can be done in such a case is for the first class to borrow of 
 the second, which only makes private debts instead of public ones 
 a much more burdensome condition of things for the national 
 industry. The wiser modern method is for the State to borrow 
 the unemployed capital and leave the employed capital intact, 
 then imposing a moderate tax which can be paid out of annual 
 income. If the expenditure in question is an investment, it pre- 
 sumably pays for itself in time without requiring taxation. 
 
 This brings us to the relation between taxes and debts. Taxes 
 should never be so heavy that they cannot be paid easily out of 
 annual income. If they trench upon national capital, they derange 
 private industries disastrously because they are imposed upon all 
 without regard to the nature of their investments. But while 
 taxes cannot safely exceed the national disposable surplus for each 
 year, it does not follow that the State may not take capital as well
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 585 
 
 as surplus for its undertakings; only this capital must be taken 
 from those who have uninvested capital. This cannot be done by 
 any method of general contribution like taxation. It can only be 
 done by public loans. Whether the loan is a wise thing or not 
 depends altogether on the nature of the State's investment. If 
 the State takes this capital ever so wisely and wastes it, the people 
 have lost just so much capital. If, on the other hand, the State 
 takes capital which was uninvested and therefore unproductive, 
 and invests it in a profitable undertaking, the net result to society 
 is an additional profit. Public debts are no indication of national 
 poverty. Whether a nation is growing poorer or not depends not 
 on its indebtedness, but on its productiveness relatively to its ex- 
 penditures. Public debts are not a good thing in and of them- 
 selves, but they have incidental advantages which offset some of 
 their disadvantages. 
 
 Having noticed the natural limits of both taxation and borrow- 
 ing, we have now to ask, What kind of expenditures should be pro- 
 vided for by each ? In general the answer is easy, though details 
 are troublesome at times. Ordinary expenditures, that is, those 
 which recur with sufficient regularity so that they can be foreseen 
 and estimated in advance, if not provided for by receipts from 
 domains and industries, must be met by taxation. If the State 
 cannot do this, it is a confession that ordinary expenditures are in 
 excess of the disposable income surplus of the nation, a state of 
 things which means bankruptcy if continued long enough. 
 
 Extraordinary expenditures, such as national misfortunes 
 war, flood, etc., and public investments, railways, city gas 
 works, etc., should be met by loans. The function of loans 
 thus becomes a double one: (i) the distribution of unavoidable 
 losses, so that industry is as little disturbed as possible; and (2) the 
 investment of national uninvested capital in productive public 
 enterprises. 
 
 There is a tendency, springing out of fright partly premature, to place 
 undue constitutional restrictions upon the power to create debts. This 
 tendency ought to be checked. It places states and cities at a disadvantage 
 as compared with private corporations. It also tends to throw into the hands 
 of private corporations enterprises which cannot be paid for out of cue
 
 586 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 year's revenues, and yet might advantageously be acquired by the public. 
 At the present time excessive limitations, unworthy of a free people, make 
 it impossible for some cities to carry out necessary public improvements, 
 although these improvements would not impose the slightest real burden upon 
 the taxpayers. In Chicago recently, to take one of many examples which 
 might be cited, after a prolonged and exceedingly expensive campaign for 
 the improvement of the street-car service, the city was prevented from carry- 
 ing out a carefully devised plan of reform by a court decision which held 
 that an issue of street railway certificates increased the indebtedness of the 
 city beyond the limitations prescribed by the constitution. Provision should 
 be made for the extinction of all debts within thirty-five years, or say forty 
 as a maximum, that the present may not unduly burden the future; and 
 especial precaution should be taken against hasty action in incurring in- 
 debtedness. But rigid limitations which prevent municipalities from off- 
 setting part of their debt by the value of waterworks, lighting plants, and 
 other assets which yield a monetary return, have no place in a scientific sys- 
 tem of public finance. 
 
 PERMANENT REGULAR REVENUES 
 
 The Public Domain. By domains we usually mean agricul- 
 tural and mineral land and forests owned by the State and man- 
 aged in the interest of the public revenue, although we might 
 logically subsume under the term the streets and other public 
 property of cities, with all those valuable franchises and privileges 
 which go with them. As appears from Table I, the revenues from 
 this source constituted less than i per cent of the total receipts 
 in 1902, and if the corresponding expenditures were shown, the 
 net earnings of the public domain would appear even smaller, 
 possibly a minus quantity. Taxation is the great source of public 
 revenue to-day. 
 
 Until a comparatively recent date this was not the case. In 
 early feudal times the king had large estates of his own from the 
 produce of which the government was largely supported, and 
 although he had certain military rights over his subjects, he had 
 very limited rights over their property. Later, the king became a 
 public rather than a private person, and a large part of the crown 
 estate became the property of the public; but even then taxation 
 was relatively unimportant, and the State relied principally in times 
 of peace upon fines, escheats, fees, crown prerogatives, or certain 
 dues which the king was entitled to collect as of his own right,
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 587 
 
 and upon the proceeds of the public domain. Blackstone, the 
 great English jurist, writing in 1765, classified taxation among 
 the "extraordinary" revenues of the sovereign; and in some of 
 the German principalities the government was enabled to get along 
 without taxation in times of peace, down to the close of the eight- 
 eenth century. Real democracy not yet having been achieved, 
 the people distrusted taxation and resented its imposition, while 
 the sovereign wisely clung to that species of revenue which was 
 independent of the people's caprice. " The public domains," 
 said Bodin, the great political philosopher of France in the latter 
 part of the sixteenth century, "should be holy, sacred, and in- 
 alienable either by grant or by prescription." 
 
 But as democracy developed and the representatives of the 
 people gained control of the finances, a new policy was everywhere 
 adopted. If State management was uneconomical and wasteful, 
 and if the government could obtain all the revenue needed by taxa- 
 tion, why preserve the wasteful methods of management, why 
 not turn public property into private property, to be developed and 
 multiplied through the vitalizing force of individual self-interest? 
 The great truth was realized that the property of individuals when 
 su bject to taxation and regulation is no less part of tlie great patri- 
 mony of the State than those lands and forests whose title is retained 
 by the government itself. This doctrine was generally accepted by 
 the greater countries of the world during the eighteenth century, 
 so that Adam Smith, in defending it in 1776, was able to write that 
 "there is not at present, in Europe, any civilized state of any kind 
 which derives the greater part of its public revenue from the rent of 
 lands which are the property of the state. ..." This philosophy 
 was dominant when our national goveri ment was created in 1 789, 
 and has guided our national policy ever since. 
 
 Land Policy of the United States. By exploration and occu- 
 pancy, war, and various cessions, the federal government has 
 acquired, since the Revolutionary War, a magnificent domain of 
 2,252,244 square miles, details concerning whose disposition may 
 be found in Table III, p. 589. Now, while we have consistently 
 followed the doctrine of alienation until very recent years, trying, 
 apparently, to get rid of the public domain as rapidly as possible,
 
 588 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 one observes historically a very important change in the manner 
 of development. In the early years of the Republic, large reve- 
 nues were expected from the sale of public lands; it was the finan- 
 cial side which, according to Alexander Hamilton, claimed ''pri- 
 mary attention." l Until about 1800, the policy was to sell the 
 land in large blocks, even though it went to speculators; this was 
 followed by an attempt to sell small holdings to actual settlers, 
 the credit system being used with disastrous results; later (1830), 
 the preemption policy was introduced by which bona fide home 
 makers were given certain advantages in purchase; and finally 
 came the Homestead Act of 1862, the Timber Culture Act of 1873 
 (now repealed), and the other less important laws by which actual 
 settlers can obtain homes practically free of cost. Our original 
 aim was to develop the country as rapidly as possible, and secure 
 as much revenue as possible from the sale of public lands. We 
 still aim to develop the country, but the idea of profit has been 
 replaced by the more humanitarian policy of giving land to the 
 landless. To exaggerate the evolution of policy for the sake of 
 emphasis, it may be said that we began with a productive policy, 
 and modified it with a distributive policy; that in the beginning 
 our object was the greatest good, while now it is the greatest good 
 to the greatest number, or, in terms more appropriate to the exact 
 case in hand, the greatest possible use of the public domain con- 
 sistent with widespread participation in that use. 
 
 The policy of national development regardless of immediate 
 revenue to the government has been also carried out by enormous 
 grants of lands for the endowment of education and the subsidiza- 
 tion of canal, railway, and internal improvement companies. Our 
 public lands have been used for expenditure rather than revenue, 
 for bounties rather than profits. Just what has been done with 
 the public domain is shown in Table III, which should be care- 
 fully studied. On the mainland of the United States we still (1007) 
 have left nearly one hah 5 as much land as we have disposed of, 
 unreserved, and still unappropriated; while if we take account of 
 Alaska and public reservations, the government might yet, as 
 was said some years ago, "repeat its sales and gratuities acre for 
 1 Quoted by Donaldson in The Public Domain, p. 198.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 
 
 589 
 
 acre, without exhausting its reserves of land." But, of course, 
 the best of the lands have gone. On June 30, 1907, there still were 
 left unappropriated and unreserved 774,438,420 acres, although 
 368,028,850 acres of this area were situated in Alaska, unsurveyed 
 and of very doubtful value. 
 
 TABLE III 
 DISPOSITION OF PUBLIC DOMAIN: JUNE 30, 1904 
 
 DISPOSITION 
 
 ACRES 
 
 1. Homestead and timber culture entries final 106,240,464.25 
 
 2. Pending homestead entries final and commuted . 39,525,840.00 
 
 3. Private land claims scrip and other 34,604,827.84 
 
 4. Allotment to individual Indians, and half-breed 
 
 scrip 14,408,079.86 
 
 5. School and agricultural college grants 76,731,243.00 
 
 6. Miscellaneous grants to states and territories 
 
 (partly educational) 87,305,203.05 
 
 7. Wagon-road construction grants 2,867,474.49 
 
 8. Canal construction grants 4,598,698.32 
 
 9. River improvement grants 2,246,251.91 
 
 10. Railroad construction grants 117,550,292.37 
 
 11. Cash sales Indian cessions, mineral lands, timber 
 
 and stone claims, and miscellaneous cash sales. . 287,001,612.29 
 
 Total alienated, excluding Alaska 773>79>987-38 
 
 12. Reservations forest, reclamation, parks, military, 
 
 Indian 194,587,475.62 
 
 Total alienated and reserved, excluding Alaska. 967,667,463.00 
 
 13. Area unappropriated and unreserved, excluding 
 
 Alaska 473,836,402.00 
 
 14. Area unappropriated and unreserved in Alaska . . . 368,035, 975 .00 
 
 Total unappropriated and unreserved 841,872,377.00 
 
 15. Total land surface in public domain, including 
 
 Alaska 1,809,539,840.00 
 
 16. Total land and water surface in public domain, in- 
 
 cluding Alaska 1,884,021,760.00 
 
 Forest Lands. The policy of alienation, while on the whole 
 sound, is subject to certain limitations which it is very important
 
 590 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 to note. First of these is the case of forests. The ruthless denuda- 
 tion of our timber lands, the striking advance in the price of lumber 
 indicating that the supply has not kept pace with the demand, and 
 the meteoric development and rapid decline of the lumber industry 
 in many localities of the Northwest, all combine to demonstrate 
 that alienation and private ownership have failed to produce that 
 careful industrial management which conduces to the greatest 
 use and the greatest good in the long run. More important still, 
 we have come to realize that the most productive use of other great 
 natural resources has not been subserved by the private ownership 
 of the forests. Climate and rainfall, the regular flow of streams, 
 the success of the great irrigation works which we are buildingj 
 and the proper development of our mines, all depend more or 
 less upon the permanent preservation of our forests; but private 
 ownership and management in the past has led to destruction, 
 not preservation. 
 
 The United States awoke very slowly to these truths. Prussia 
 abandoned the policy of disposing of forest lands in 1 83 1 . France 
 and Austria began to increase their forest holdings about 1870. 
 But it was not until 1876, in the United States, that an awakened 
 interest showed itself in a congressional appropriation of two thou- 
 sand dollars for the purpose of employing "a competent man 
 to investigate timber conditions in the United States." In 1881 
 a Division of Forestry was created in the Department of Agri- 
 culture which expanded into the Bureau of Forestry in 1901, and 
 into the Forest Service in 1905. In 1891 a forward step was 
 taken by the passage of an act authorizing the President to 
 establish forest reserves; and in the same year the first forest 
 reserve was established. In November, 1907, the area of the 
 national forest reserves had increased to 159,439,979 acres; the 
 forest service had developed to a point where it was able to 
 care for the management of this vast national industry, and to 
 cooperate further with private owners in establishing the principles 
 of scientific forestry, while the policy of alienation has been 
 modified to an extent amounting almost to reversal. Instead of 
 selling forests, tJie government is now permitting timber to be cut in 
 a way to preserve the forests. The revenue from this source at the
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 591 
 
 present time is nearly $2,000,000, but that is a secondary con- 
 sideration. The important point is that the government has 
 demonstrated its ability to manage the forests along lines at once 
 scientific and commercial. In many European countries, how- 
 ever, a greater revenue is secured from the forests. In France, 
 for example, the public forests cover nearly 18 per cent of the 
 entire land surface of the country, and yield approximately, it 
 is reported, $2.50 per acre annually, giving a revenue of about 
 $59,000,000 a year. "The Prussian budget for 1903 estimated 
 the gross receipts from forests at 106,854,000 marks, and the net 
 receipts at 60,000,000 marks." In the United States at present 
 25 per cent of what is received, according to law, goes to the states 
 and territories in which the reserves are situated for public roads 
 and schools? It is estimated that in a few years the reserves will 
 yield not less than $5,000,000 a year. 
 
 Experience has shown that the public ownership and manage- 
 ment of forests is far more efficient than private ownership and 
 management. This is due to the length of time required to realize 
 upon investments in this industry, its routine character, the large 
 area one man can supervise, and, perhaps chiefly to the fact that 
 the government in its management takes into account the interests 
 of the community as a whole. Although private corporations may 
 make plans for a long period of time, they are less desirable owners 
 and managers, especially in the last particular. The property tax, 
 as now levied, is one of the greatest enemies of rational forestry 
 by private owners. The State spends millions of dollars to pre- 
 serve the forests, and yet enforces a tax that puts a premium 
 upon their destruction. 
 
 Mineral Lands. Our experience with timber lands is im- 
 portant as showing that private ownership of some kinds of 
 land has not resulted in the greatest or wisest use of that land. 
 Our experience with mineral lands demonstrates that the policy 
 of disposing of public lands in small holdings, free of cost or at 
 prices far below their real value, has not led to a widespread partici- 
 pation in the use and profit of those lands. The reason for this, 
 broadly speaking, is that our policy of alienation in small hold- 
 ings conflicts with the requirements and necessities of modern 
 industry. In disposing of our lands we have tried to balk the
 
 592 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 corporation and the speculator in order to subsidize the settler and 
 home builder. For instance, we have made the recipients of 
 homesteads and mineral claims swear that they are not acting as 
 agents "for any person, corporation, or syndicate" or "in collusion 
 with any person, corporation, or syndicate, to give them the benefit 
 of the land entered," and that the land is not being secured "for 
 the purpose of speculation." Yet for purposes of grazing and in 
 less degree for mining and lumbering, modern industrial methods 
 require that large tracts of land shall be worked together, and that 
 individual claims shall be consolidated. The core of the difficulty 
 has been well described by President Roosevelt in these words: 
 "It is a scandal to maintain laws which sound well but which 
 make fraud the key without which great natural resources must 
 remain closed. The law should give individuals and corporations, 
 under proper government regulation and control, the right to work 
 bodies of coal lands large enough for profitable development." 
 And the President thereafter recommends that laws shall be passed 
 which shall authorize the leasing, instead of the complete alienation, 
 of coal, oil, and gas rights, as well as grazing rights on the public 
 domain. Bills are now pending in Congress which look to the 
 leasing of mineral lands rather than their sale, and there is little 
 doubt that the policy of complete alienation will be sooner or later 
 followed by a royalty or rental system. 
 
 Already the royalty system has been adopted by some of the 
 commonwealth governments, and year by year the policy of com- 
 plete alienation is more and more restricted. In a few years, in 
 some of the Western states, these leases will probably provide 
 enormous revenues. The state of Minnesota, for instance, in 
 which the royalty system has been inaugurated, received $163,833 
 from royalties, and $31,985 from prospecting permits and fifty-year 
 leases in the fiscal year ending July 31, 1907. The auditor of the 
 state, in speaking of the Vermilion and Messabe iron ranges, says 
 that on contracts now in existence perhaps one hundred million 
 dollars will be realized for the school and university funds. 1 
 
 Auditor's Report for 1905-1906, p. liv. Data given in the Preliminary Re- 
 port of the Minnesota Tax Commission for 1907, Chap. V, however, seem to 
 indicate that $50,000,000 would be a safer estimate.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 
 
 593 
 
 The Success of our Land Policy. In a rough, general way, 
 our land policy has been a success, as is shown by the unprece- 
 dented and almost feverish development of the country in the last 
 century, with the creation of a fund of taxable values which makes 
 it an easy matter for the state governments to raise all the revenue 
 which they need. But in some respects it has signally failed. In 
 the first place it has not paid : more money has been spent for the 
 purchase, survey, and care of the public lands than has been re- 
 ceived from their sale and lease. In the second place, certain 
 kinds of lands, as we have shown, should not have been alienated. 
 And in the third place, our efforts to give land to the landless have 
 bred an immense amount of corruption, fostered speculation, en- 
 dowed private monopoly with public wealth, and pauperized whole 
 communities. One has only to recall the recent convictions of 
 public officers for land frauds, and to read the report of the Com- 
 mission on Public Lands, to which specific reference is given at 
 the end of the chapter, to appreciate the truth of all these charges. 
 The desert land law and the commutation clause of the Homestead 
 Act, they tell us, operate far too often "to bring about land mo- 
 nopoly rather than to multiply small holdings by actual settlers." 
 ... "In many localities, and perhaps in general, a larger pro- 
 portion of the public land is passing into the hands of speculators 
 and corporations than into those of actual settlers who are making 
 homes." . . . "Nearly everywhere the large landowner has suc- 
 ceeded in monopolizing the best tracts, whether of timber or of 
 agricultural land." . . . "Your commission has had inquiries 
 made as to how a number of estates, selected haphazard, have 
 been acquired. Almost without exception, collusion or evasion 
 of the letter and spirit of the land laws was involved." . . . "The 
 fundamental fact that characterizes the present situation is this: 
 that the number of patents issued is increasing out of all propor- 
 tion to the number of new homes." 
 
 Possibly the most important lesson to be derived from the his- 
 tory of our landed domain is the vital truth that the government 
 cannot give away valuable lands or sell them at prices far below 
 their real value without subsidizing the speculator, endowing 
 monopoly, and pauperizing the people. The poorer classes derive
 
 594 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 no real benefit from this indiscriminate public charity. As 
 Secretary of the Interior Hitchcock said in 1905, in discussing 
 the Timber and Stone Act: 1 "Many transfers of land patented 
 under this law are made immediately upon completion of title to 
 individuals and companies. In this way a monopoly of the timber 
 supplies of the public-land states is being created by systematic 
 collusion. ... It has been urged in behalf of this act that it 
 enables poor men to enjoy the bounty of the government by ob- 
 taining tracts of land which they can afterwards sell with advan- 
 tage. A careful study seems to show, on the contrary, that the 
 original entrymen rarely realize more than ordinary wages for the 
 time spent in making the entry and completing the transfer. The 
 corporations which ultimately secure title usually absorb by far 
 the greater part of the profit." When Uncle Sam was rich enough 
 
 or was supposed to be rich enough to provide us all with a 
 farm, the policy of giving avray the public domain appeared to be 
 in harmony with the principle of equality of opportunity. But 
 when the supply is far below the demand, those who receive gifts 
 by lot or similar methods are in receipt of special privileges. 
 What once seemed fair has, in the course of economic evolution, 
 become unfair and demoralizing. 
 
 Our conclusion may be formulated in the following general rule : 
 only those lands should be wholly alienated whose use and devel- 
 opment under private ownership lead neither to monopoly nor to 
 exhaustion and waste. Or, in more concrete terms, remem- 
 bering that the maxim applies only to those lands left to the gov- 
 ernment, and to the majority of cases, not to every specific case, 
 
 the rule for agricultural lands should be private ownership and 
 management, for forest lands State ownership and management, 
 for mining and grazing lands State ownership and private man- 
 agement under a lease or royalty system, by which the State shall 
 secure a share of the profits and retain a large amount of regulation 
 and control. In disposing of its lands the government should 
 endeavor to charge value received, as gifts of valuable land, or sale 
 at inelastic tariffs of prices which place an extreme valuation upon 
 some tracts and an utterly inadequate valuation upon others, lead 
 
 1 Report of the Secretary of the Interior, 1905, p. 331.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 595 
 
 to speculation and monopoly, having most of the demoralizing 
 features of a public lottery in which the prizes are distributed 
 partly by chance and partly in accordance with the cunning, 
 chicanery, and unscrupulousness of the participators. Under 
 existing conditions the poorer classes of society get almost none 
 of the valuable lands. Charge value received, and the people, the 
 masses, get their share in the revenues flowing to the public treas- 
 ury, in reduced taxes, and more generous expenditures for educa- 
 tional, protective, and developmental purposes. 
 
 Land Nationalization and Municipalization. In recent years 
 both state and national legislation has shown a decided trend 
 toward the adoption of methods which will yield both greater 
 revenue and greater control of those varied forms of national 
 wealth which we collectively designate "land." The object of 
 this legislation is to prevent monopoly and give to society a share 
 in the land values created by social growth. One of the most in- 
 genious plans for securing this end ever proposed is the single-tax 
 scheme defended with great eloquence and earnestness by the late 
 Henry George. His scheme, usually called "the single tax," is 
 stated thus in his own words, printed in his organ, The Standard: 
 
 " The Standard advocates the abolition of al! taxes upon industry and the 
 products of industry, and the taking, by taxation upon land values, irrespec- 
 tive of improvements, of the annual rental value of all those various forms of 
 natural opportunities embraced under the general term 'land.' 
 
 "We hold that to tax labor or its products is to discourage industry. 
 We hold that to tax land values to their full amount will render it impossible 
 for any man to exact from others a price for the privilege of using those 
 bounties of nature in which all living men have an equal right of use; that 
 it will compel every individual controlling natural opportunities to utilize 
 them by employment of labor or abandon them to others; that it will thus 
 provide opportunities of work for all men and secure to each the full reward 
 of his labor; and that as a result involuntary poverty will be abolished, and 
 the greed, intemperance, and vice that spring from poverty and the dread of 
 poverty will be swept away." 
 
 Mr. George's proposition rests upon an extreme application of 
 the doctrines of individualism and natural rights. Man, he holds, 
 has an inalienable and equal right to live, and consequently an 
 inalienable and equal right to those natural agents which we call
 
 596 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 land, and without which human life cannot exist. This right 
 which attaches to the individual cannot be abrogated by law or 
 custom, nor can it be alienated by one generation or set of law 
 givers. Moreover, it is an equal right. A, B, and C each have a 
 right to the soil, but A has no right to better soil than B or C ; in 
 consequence of which that part of land values which arises from 
 the differential qualities of land belongs to society as a whole, and 
 not to particular individuals. But the differential value of land 
 expresses itself in the economic rent which it yields, and conse- 
 quently, if society seizes this rent by taxation, it will satisfy the 
 demands of the doctrine of natural rights, while leaving the actual 
 management and exploitation of land in the hands of individual 
 occupiers, thus avoiding the perils of direct public management. 
 
 Man also has an unalienable right, Mr. George held, to the fruits 
 of his own labor. As the outcome of this right, Mr. George con- 
 cluded that ordinary taxation upon property other than land, upon 
 the product of labor as distinguished from land, the gift of God, is 
 robbery. In his view it is as immoral to levy an ordinary tax as it 
 is criminal to fail to tax that surplus which attaches to the better 
 classes of lands, and which we call economic rent. 
 
 The policy embodied in Mr. George's scheme differs funda- 
 mentally from the policy which we have seen creeping into recent 
 legislation. The latter purposes to reserve only a part of the 
 value given to some forms of land by social development. Mr. 
 George proposes to confiscate all of "the unearned increment." 
 Most important of all, the former proposition applies only to the 
 future unearned increment, and purposes only to take a part, and 
 that only after fair notice is given. Mr. George proposes to take 
 all the unearned increment, past and present, and that whether 
 the present owners have been encouraged to believe that they 
 might be permitted to appropriate the whole unearned increment 
 or not. Herein lies the essential injustice of Mr. George's scheme. 
 As a nation we have induced immigrants and settlers to take up 
 lands, clear them, and develop them with their labor and toil, with 
 the promise that the values thus created by themselves and their 
 neighbors should belong to them. Their risks and their sacrifices 
 have been great. Even if we assume that the State made a mistake
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 597 
 
 in pursuing this policy, the results of the mistake must be cheer- 
 fully borne by the party at fault, the State itself. 
 
 Mr. George not only proposes to confiscate all economic rent 
 without compensation, and to abolish all other forms of taxation, 
 but the assertion is made in explanation and justification of the 
 policy that it will abolish poverty. Such a policy might, indeed, 
 prevent landowners, who do not care to use their land, from keep- 
 ing it out of the hands of those who would use it; but how it would 
 effect all the other predicted blessings is difficult for most people to 
 comprehend. In the first place, it is difficult to imagine how pure 
 economic rent of agricultural land can be separated in practice 
 from the annual value of the separable improvements on the land. 
 But apart from this difficulty, the appropriation of economic rent 
 by the public without compensation to the owners will probably 
 never appeal to the conscience of the American public as a just 
 thing to do. No abstract reasoning, based on "natural rights," 
 will persuade a modern nation to so radical a step. This honestly 
 and earnestly advocated policy is only one more illustration of the 
 danger of basing social reasoning on any theory of "natural 
 rights." 
 
 In cities it is easier to separate the pure economic rent from the 
 earnings of improvements, such as buildings. Moreover, it is in 
 cities that the principal evils attendant on private landholding 
 are discoverable. Therefore the objections to land nationalization 
 do not in the same degree apply to land municipalization. Many 
 who will reject the one will favor the other. Even here, however, 
 it is well to proceed very cautiously. Confiscation, at any rate, 
 should not be tolerated. If great and expensive changes along 
 this line should approve themselves to the people, the burden of 
 the changes should be widely diffused throughout the community 
 by means of inheritance and other taxes. 1 
 
 Public Industries. In the beginning, let us briefly pass in 
 review the principal classes of industrial enterprise in which the 
 modern State engages for the satisfaction of other than State 
 wants; because, obviously, we are not concerned with enterprises 
 like the government printing office, the government navy yards. 
 1 See pp. 364 and 365 for further discussion of the single tax.
 
 598 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 and in general, those incidental industries whose products the 
 government consumes but does not regularly sell. 
 
 I. First, we find States like Switzerland monopolizing the manu- 
 facture of alcohol and certain alcoholic beverages, Japan monopo- 
 lizing the opium traffic in Formosa, or commonwealths like South 
 Carolina engaging in the retail distribution of intoxicating bever- 
 ages. 1 The purpose of the State in engaging in such industries is 
 primarily sumptuary; it is desired to regulate the traffic almost 
 to the point of suppression, perhaps. Ordinarily a good revenue 
 would be secured, but revenue is a very secondary consideration. 
 Prices will be placed above the level of highest net profit, and not 
 improbably the ideal of regulating consumption will be so vigor- 
 ously pursued that profits will disappear altogether. 
 
 II. Secondly, we have the group of so-called "fiscal monopolies." 
 France, for instance, monopolizes the manufacture of matches, 
 cigarettes, and tobacco in general; Japan 2 has recently gone 
 farther than any other country in the creation of fiscal monopolies ; 
 while Prussia, Austria, Italy, Spain, and other European countries 
 maintain public lotteries as did many of the American colonies 
 during the eighteenth century. The primary object of the State 
 in undertaking these enterprises is public revenue, gain; and 
 naturally a monopoly price is charged, the price which will yield 
 the greatest net revenue. 
 
 III. Next, we have a group of enterprises consisting principally 
 of the so-called "natural monopolies," which the State undertakes 
 not for suppression, not for profit, but primarily for regulation 
 to regulate the quality of the product, as in the case of water; to 
 maintain effectively what have been called "equitable conditions 
 for the prosecution of private business," as in the case of railways; 
 to prevent monopolistic extortion and corporate abuse, as in the 
 case of lighting companies, the post office, the telegraph, and the 
 telephone; or to prevent crime and preserve intact the foundations 
 of commercial prosperity, as in the monopoly of coinage. The 
 charges here are ordinarily adjusted to either the "revenue" or the 
 
 1 Since writing the above, South Carolina has abandoned the dispensary 
 system. 
 
 * Cf. recent magazine articles.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 599 
 
 "cost" principle, that is to say, the State will either aim to make a 
 fair business profit such as is secured in competitive private enter- 
 prises, or it will endeavor approximately to meet expenses by 
 adjusting its charges to the cost of production. England, France, 
 and Germany, in ordinary years, obtain handsome revenues from 
 their respective postal departments, but in the United States the 
 accounts of the Post Office Department show a regular annual 
 deficit ($6,653,282 in the fiscal year 1906-1907), and taking the 
 world over, the cost principle in this group of industries is probably 
 more common than the revenue principle, and deficits more com- 
 mon than net profits. In the United States the post office has 
 always been regarded as a developmental agency rather than a 
 business enterprise, and might more logically, perhaps, be included 
 in the next category. 
 
 IV. Finally, we have a large and heterogeneous group of in- 
 dustries which are maintained principally for service, for their edu- 
 cational and developmental influence, not primarily for regulation, 
 and not at all for profit, but "for the public good." We include 
 here not only schools and educational institutions of all kinds, but 
 roads and canals; the savings banks and public pawn shops main- 
 tained in several countries of continental Europe; workingmen's 
 insurance as developed by Germany, Austria, and several of the 
 Australian colonies; and the model manufacturing establishments 
 such as France maintains for the production of tapestries and fine 
 porcelains. In this group charges will sink to a minimum, and in 
 some lines of enterprise, such as education, practically disappear. 
 Revenue here is not only a minor, but is almost a negligible, 
 consideration. 
 
 A brief consideration of the incomplete list of State industries 
 given above brings out several important truths. In the first place, 
 it is evident that only a few of these industries, the fiscal monopo- 
 lies, have been taken over by the State for the purpose of revenue, 
 and fiscal monopolies are decreasing rather than increasing in 
 relative importance. In the second place, it is equally as clear 
 that, on the whole, public industries are sources of expense and 
 not of profit. When Professor Bastable, for example, tells us that 
 in England, in the fiscal year 1893-1894, only 6 per cent of the
 
 600 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 national revenue came from public industries and other non-tax 
 sources, that in the local revenues of England and Wales (1891- 
 1892) taxation stood to other sources of revenue in the ratio of five 
 to one, that in Prussia about 20 per cent of the national reve- 
 nue comes from the domain and industrial enterprises, and in 
 India something less than 50 per cent from "quasi-private sources 
 of revenue," he is careful to warn us that the statistics take no 
 cognizance of interest payments chargeable to the several indus- 
 tries, or of depreciation, or of related industries in which deficits 
 and not profits were secured. When estimating the importance of 
 railway earnings in the revenue account, no cognizance is ordi- 
 narily taken of the canal deficit. In the third place, we perceive 
 from the nature of the industries that they cannot wisely be oper- 
 ated for profit in many cases. Education, for instance, has been 
 taken over by the State for the very purpose of charging less than 
 the cost of the service. The unquestionable tendency is for the 
 prices of goods and services supplied by a democratic State to sink 
 below the cost of production, and this, in itself, is neither good nor 
 bad, fortunate nor unfortunate. The public financier, in adjusting 
 the charges, must not look to profit. His only aim is the solus 
 populi, and this policy requires here a prohibitive price, there a 
 cost price, and again free service. Finally, it appears, the problem 
 of public charges can be settled only with reference to a particular 
 time, place, and industry. England finds it expedient to raise a 
 handsome revenue from her post office, while the United States 
 manages our post office at a loss. Waterworks are successfully 
 conducted by most of the large American municipalities, but public 
 lighting experiments in this country have not been equally suc- 
 cessful. India raises half of her revenues from non-tax sources 
 largely because heavy taxation of the ordinary kind would be im- 
 possible. The French tobacco monopoly succeeds because the 
 French government can supervise and trace almost every pound 
 of tobacco grown in France. In the United States this would be 
 impossible. 
 
 Although we cannot decide in a general way what theory of 
 charges should be followed in particular public industries, it is 
 possible to lay down general rules which will assist in reaching a
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 6oi 
 
 correct conclusion in specific cases. Assuming that the industry 
 in question supplies a service rather than a commodity, merely to 
 save words in the discussion, we must first of all inquire: (a) Is 
 the service helpful or harmful in its net social effect ? According 
 as it is one or the other, we will incline in our charges toward the 
 gratuity principle or the prohibitive principle. If harmful, how- 
 ever, it is plain that we must not make the charges high enough to 
 encourage smuggling or illicit manufacture. If helpful, on the 
 other hand, we cannot at once decide upon the gratuity principle, 
 but must inquire farther, (6) How, generally, is the service en- 
 joyed ? If only a small portion of the community enjoys the serv- 
 ice, it would usually be unjust to charge less than cost, because 
 the deficit would be borne by general taxation falling upon the 
 entire community, unless, indeed, the benefit to one restricted class 
 is seen to be of advantage to the whole community, in such a 
 degree that the rest of the community is willing to bear the deficit, 
 as in the case of public charity. 
 
 (c) Assuming that the service benefits the whole community, 
 this is still not sufficient to justify a charge less than the cost of pro- 
 duction. The problem is one of comparative costs. We must in- 
 quire whether greater benefit would not be secured by charging 
 enough to raise a profit and then distributing that profit through 
 the maintenance of some other gratuitous enterprise, or, if the tax 
 system weighs heavily on the poor, by remitting taxation to the 
 extent of the profit, (d) If all these questions are answered in 
 favor of the gratuity principle, we still must consider, What effect 
 will gratuitous service have upon the cost of the service ? Will it 
 encourage wastefulness? Free city water, for example, would 
 probably prove impracticable because of waste, but free parks or 
 free education do not lead to inordinate or unnecessary consump- 
 tion. The question is a vital one, but it is not always to be an- 
 swered one way, as some critics of government ownership seem to 
 believe, (e) Closely related to the above, is the question of pauper- 
 ization. Some things the State may safely give away, and some 
 not. The modern city, for example, may give band concerts free, 
 in our view, to the undoubted edification of the community; but in 
 Rome the public games demoralized the populace. (/) Finally,
 
 602 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 we have to ask, What effect will gratuitous service have on in- 
 comes ? Henry George proposed that our cities should operate the 
 street car lines gratuitously, and the argument in its favor is far 
 stronger than might be expected on first thought. But what effect 
 would this gratuitous service have upon the incomes of the laboring 
 classes ? Take the case of the worker in New York City earning 
 $3.00 a day. Will his wages remain at $3.00, if street car service 
 is offered free of charge ? Will not the migration to New York be 
 increased, so that wages will fall? And may not the gain ulti- 
 mately fall to owners of house property in the form of enhanced 
 rents ? 
 
 All these questions must be answered before the tariff of charges 
 can be adopted, and it is plain that the answers will be determined 
 by the particular conditions of time, industry, and place, particu- 
 larly by the character of the industry. The nearest approach to a 
 general rule which can be formulated, may be stated as follows: 
 In proportion as a service or commodity tends to the upbuilding of 
 character and personality, we should, so far as fiscal conditions per- 
 mit, gradually move in the direction of the principle of gratuitous 
 service. If the service or commodity itself is widely consumed and 
 is as desirable as anything among vendible commodities, particularly 
 if large consumption is desirable and waste in consumption does not 
 become excessive, the principle of gratuitous service may be recom- 
 mended. 
 
 Limitations of space prevent further treatment of the subject of 
 public industries. The important thing to understand is that the 
 moment an industry is taken over by the government, that moment 
 the question of profit which is the vital consideration under 
 private management becomes of secondary importance, sub- 
 ordinate to questions of public policy; and the interjection of 
 public policy into the determination of prices or charges, creates a 
 problem whose complexity and difficulty can scarcely be exag- 
 gerated. At the present time, for instance, we do not even know 
 whether our second class postal rates pay for the cost of carriage 
 and delivery of second class matter, to say nothing of the question 
 whether such matter ought to be carried at less than cost. Just 
 now the indications are that the State will take over an increasing
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 603 
 
 number of industries, or at least exert a constantly increasing in- 
 fluence upon the rates and charges of quasi-public industries. 
 Under these circumstances our present duty is to institute, both in 
 public and quasi-public industries, a thoroughgoing system of cost 
 accounting, so that we shall understand upon what footing each 
 branch of the industry rests. Our second duty, which falls pri- 
 marily upon economists and statesmen, is to develop a far more 
 satisfactory theory of public charges, for at the present time we 
 hardly understand the many factors that must be considered in 
 this problem, much less the net meaning or resultant of these 
 factors. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. What proportion of the public receipts comes from the public domains? 
 What gives importance to the question of revenue from government owner- 
 ship? 
 
 2. Are public debts a burden when represented by paying investments? 
 by non-revenue-bearing investments ? 
 
 3. Do State debts indicate impoverishment of the people? Why? 
 
 4. What expenditures should be met by taxation? by loans? What is 
 the natural limit of each? 
 
 5. How was the State supported in primitive times? What connection 
 is there between taxation and representative government? 
 
 6. What has been the principal aim of the United States in the manage- 
 ment of public lands? How has this aim changed? 
 
 7. Why do the poorer classes benefit least by the homestead acts and by 
 the sale of the public lands at prices below their real value ? 
 
 8. Have as many acres of land been given to individuals by the homestead 
 and similar acts as to the railways? 
 
 9. What kinds of land should be both owned and managed by govern- 
 ment? Why? 
 
 10. What are the advantages and disadvantages of the royalty or lease 
 system ? To what kinds of land should it be applied ? 
 
 n. What conflict is there between modern industrial methods and the 
 project of giving land to the landless? 
 
 12. What connection is there between "natural right" and the single- 
 tax scheme? 
 
 13. Is there any absolute, inalienable right to life? to anything? 
 
 14. Should State industries be managed so as to yield a profit? Is a 
 profit inconsistent with good State management? Is any general tendency, 
 with respect to profits, discernible in the management of particular public 
 industries ?
 
 604 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ADAMS, H. C. Public Debts, and The Science of Finance, Part II, Book II, 
 Chap. I, "Revenue from Public Domains," pp. 237-260; Chap. II, 
 "Revenue from Public Industries," pp. 261-282. 
 
 BASTABLE, C. F. Public Finance, Book II and Book V, Chap. II, "The 
 State Domain, Lands and Forests," pp. 157-178; Chap. Ill, "The 
 Industrial Domain," pp. 179-218; Chap. IV, "The State as Capitalist, 
 Administrative Revenue," pp. 219-232. 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Selected Readings in Public Finance, Chap. IV, "The 
 Views of Bodin and Smith," pp. 50-60; Chap. V, "Revenues from 
 Domains," pp. 61-72; Chap. VI, "Revenues from Public Industries," 
 pp. 80-116. 
 
 Census Bulletins, Nos. 20, 45, 50. " Statistics of Cities," passim. 
 
 Census Report. Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, Part II and Part IV, pp. 953- 
 
 963- 
 COHN, GUSTAV. The Science of Finance, Book I, Chap. II, " The Public 
 
 Economy in Process of Growth," pp. 82-103. 
 DANIELS, W. M. The Elements of Public Finance, Part III, Chap. I, pp. 
 
 285-314; Part II, Chap. IX, "Public Income from Quasi-economic 
 
 Sources," pp. 207-223. 
 
 PLEHN, C. C. Introduction to Public Finance, Part III, pp. 278-324. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Essays in Taxatiott, Chap. IX, "Classification of 
 
 Public Revenues." 
 Senate Document No. 189, 58th Congress, 3d Session. Report of the Public 
 
 Lands Commission, pp. iii-xxiv. 
 SCOTT, W. A. The Repudiation of State Debts. 
 U. S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service. The Use Book, 1906, 
 
 passim.
 
 CHAPTER XXXIV 
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES: DERIVATIVE REVENUES, FEES, 
 SPECIAL ASSESSMENTS, AND TAXES 
 
 Definitions. If the reader will run over the classification of 
 public industries given in the preceding chapter (page 598), he 
 will notice that the corresponding payments which descend, 
 it will be remembered, from prohibitive to gratuity charges 
 fall into two main classes: those imposed upon the consumer or 
 purchaser who specially benefits by the service, and those 
 like the revenues devoted to the maintenance of education and 
 public parks imposed upon the tax-paying public generally, 
 irrespective of the benefits conferred by the service. Moreover, 
 as we move from the prohibitive to the gratuity group, there is 
 a general though not regular change in the degree and kind of 
 compulsion exercised by the State in collecting the contribution. 
 The State does not encourage the purchase of intoxicating liquors 
 under the Gothenburg system in order that the revenue may be 
 as large as possible ; it actually discourages their sale : the use of 
 the postal money order is mildly encouraged, but you may send 
 your money by express if you desire; one is not forced to marry, 
 but if one marries one is compelled to take out a marriage license; 
 and whether one uses the public schools or not, one must help 
 pay for their maintenance. Finally, it will be noticed that as the 
 element of compulsion increases, the public interest in the service 
 changes, and generally though not always increases. The wood 
 sold from the government forests is merely a commercial by- 
 product of an enterprise maintained by the government for other 
 purposes; the marriage license fee benefits the individual, but is 
 imposed primarily to protect the morals of the community; while 
 the tax to maintain the public schools is paid solely for the purpose 
 of benefiting the general public. 
 
 605
 
 606 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 There are, then, three general principles of classification: (a) 
 the assignability of the benefit of the service to an individual; 
 (6) the degree of compulsion exercised by the State; (c) the 
 degree and kind of public interest involved in the service. The 
 more voluntary payments for the more commercial services made 
 by persons who receive a special benefit from these services, are 
 called public prices; the less voluntary payments for services in 
 which the public interest is less commercial in character, made 
 by persons who receive a special benefit from the services, are 
 called fees. Compulsory contributions, "levied in proportion 
 to the special benefits derived, to defray the cost of a 
 specific improvement to property, undertaken in the public in- 
 terest," are, in the United States, called special assessments; 
 and compulsory contributions, exacted by public authority ac- 
 cording to some general rule, without reference to the special 
 benefit conferred by the services to whose maintenance the con- 
 tributions are devoted, are called taxes. 
 
 The student is warned that little regard is paid to these distinc- 
 tions in everyday usage. The words "fees," "taxes," "licenses," 
 " tariffs," " rates," " charges," and the like are hopelessly confused; 
 and even the trained economist finds it impossible to distinguish with 
 complete success between prices, fees, and some kinds of taxes. 
 The utility of the terms is in emphasizing the important truth 
 that these great categories of public contributions must be dis- 
 tinguished and differently treated by the legislator and student, 
 by whatever terms the different categories are designated. 
 
 Fees. 1 In the exercise of its most fundamental and general 
 functions, the government frequently confers, in an incidental 
 way, special benefits upon particular individuals. Thus the courts, 
 whose function it is to administer justice in general, find that this 
 function must be performed by deciding disputes between partic- 
 ular litigants, one of whom usually benefits by the decision. 
 Now if the government is disposed to take advantage of the op- 
 
 1 Public prices have been discussed in the preceding chapter. The small 
 tuition charges paid by students in state universities offer a good illustration of 
 fees; they are non-commercial in character, semi-voluntary, and in amount 
 fall considerably short of the cost of the service.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 607 
 
 portunity, it is evident that much revenue may be raised from the 
 individuals who, in a more or less adventitious way, benefit from 
 the government activities; and where the nation is poor or the 
 people averse to taxation, much dependence will be placed upon 
 fees. As wealth increases, however, and the government becomes 
 more democratic, there is a growing disposition to support general 
 functions by general contributions taxes and the relative 
 importance of fees is likely to decline. On the other hand, there 
 is no likelihood that fees will wholly disappear, as they exercise 
 a wholesome influence in preventing waste. Court fees, for 
 instance, would probably have been abolished before this, if they 
 did not serve to prevent litigous persons from carrying their 
 quarrels to the courts for settlements. Because of this restrictive 
 and economical influence exercised by fees, they will undoubtedly 
 retain a permanent place in the public revenues of even the more 
 advanced and democratic states; but their fiscal importance 
 will probably decline. 
 
 During the colonial epoch, the fee system was much abused in 
 America, many offices being wholly maintained by fees, which 
 should have been abolished or supported by taxation. At the 
 present time, however, the evils of the system arise not from the 
 number or amount of fees, but from their connection with the sala- 
 ries of certain public officials. Many officials are allowed to keep 
 the fees which they collect in lieu of fixed salaries, and this practice 
 results in very serious evils. In the first place, some fee-paid 
 offices, particularly those of sheriff and register of deeds in popu- 
 lous districts, have come to yield princely incomes, and the scramble 
 for these rich offices constitutes a prolific source of political 
 corruption. In the second place, fee payment of public officials 
 often impels them to an excessive and pernicious activity, in which 
 their own interests and those of the commonwealth are placed in 
 direct conflict. In a few states, for instance, prosecuting at- 
 torneys are paid so much per conviction, the fee increasing with 
 the heinousness of the offense, while in many cities and villages 
 the police force and city courts are supported partially by fees 
 and fines. Under these circumstances, officials bend their activity 
 to the conviction of offenders, not to the prevention of crime and
 
 608 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the reform of the criminal; they frequently set traps for persons 
 who are likely to break the law, creating the temptation and the 
 opportunity in order that they may increase their emoluments. 
 In Wisconsin, sheriffs were for many years paid so much per 
 head for the tramps whom they fed and lodged. The system, 
 as has been said, placed a "direct premium upon vagrancy." 1 
 During the existence of this system in Wisconsin, tramps were 
 "often furnished with liquor, tobacco, and newspapers, to induce 
 them to return." Finally, the fee system has been a constant 
 and shameful corrupter of justice as dispensed by justices of the 
 peace in "the people's courts." In most states there are several 
 justice's courts open to the plaintiff who desires to bring suit. 
 In consequence, a disgraceful competition springs up, each justice 
 endeavoring to swell his business and multiply his fees by con- 
 stantly finding for the plaintiff, with the result that our judicial 
 system is thoroughly vicious at the point where perhaps it comes 
 in closest contact with the masses of the people. 
 
 The remedy is in the substitution, wherever possible, of regular 
 salaries for fee stipends, and in the institution of methods of 
 accounting which will hold public officials to strict accountability 
 for every fee collected. Fortunately, the movement of legislation, 
 while slow and obstinately fought by the politicians, is in the 
 right direction ; and in almost every state, public officials are befi^g 
 required to turn their fees into the general treasury and accept 
 instead a fixed compensation. 
 
 Special Assessments. Where the operations of the govern- 
 ment confer a special benefit upon some restricted group of in- 
 dividuals, those individuals are often led to exercise undue in- 
 fluence upon the government to secure that service, if the latter 
 is supported by appropriations from the general funds. Jobbery 
 and graft are encouraged. On the other hand, if the only way 
 the group of individuals can secure the service is by expenditure 
 of the common funds, the government or legislature often delays 
 the expenditure unduly for fear of criticism or because of unwise 
 parsimony. Thus in cities where the method of special assess- 
 
 1 T. K. Urdahl, The Fee System in the United States, p. an, et passim, from 
 which the other quotations cited in this section are taken.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 609 
 
 ment is not used, it often happens that the opening of a street 
 is delayed long after the time when it would be desirable for the 
 citizens most interested, although perhaps the latter would be 
 willing to defray the cost from their own pockets, were this 
 permitted. 
 
 A recognition of these facts in recent years has led to a striking 
 development in the United States, of the benefit principle as ex- 
 emplified in the method of special assessments. The special 
 assessment has been used sporadically in many countries for 
 several centuries, but it was first regularly used on a wide scale 
 in the United States, in the latter half of the nineteenth century. 
 Its place and importance among the regular derivative revenues 
 is shown in Table I, page 611, from which it appears that special 
 assessments aggregating nearly $40,000,000 were collected in 
 1902. This amount constituted less than 3 per cent of all the 
 derivative revenues; but as the national government collects no 
 special assessments and Massachusetts is practically the only 
 state which makes use of the special assessment in state finances, 
 the real importance of the special assessment appears more clearly 
 from an examination of its place among municipal revenues. 
 Among cities of more than 8000 inhabitants in 1903 special assess- 
 ments constituted nearly 8 per cent of the derivative revenues 
 and yielded almost one tenth as much revenue as all kinds of 
 taxation. 
 
 The special assessment has been approved by the American 
 courts because it places at least a part of the cost of the service 
 upon the beneficiaries of the service, a rule which can sometimes, 
 but not often, be violated without subjecting the government to 
 excessive and corrupting private influence. The special assess- 
 ment has appealed to the people, however, because it permits 
 public improvements to go ahead at a pace which would be im- 
 possible if taxation were the only fund for defraying the cost of 
 the improvements. Needless to say, the special assessment has 
 occasionally stimulated extravagance and premature development. 
 Thus, in New Jersey, in the last quarter of the nineteenth century, 
 several large cities were practically thrown into bankruptcy by 
 undertaking ambitious public works, in which the special assess-
 
 6 10 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ment played an important part. And in New York, under the 
 Tweed regime, the system of special assessments furnished an 
 excuse for undertaking public works in which corruption flourished, 
 and which probably would never have been undertaken, had it 
 been known in the beginning that their cost would have to be 
 partially defrayed by taxation. " The works had been carried 
 on upon a scale of audacious extravagance, and in portions of 
 the city where they were not at the time justified. Great avenues 
 were laid out and improved largely for the purpose of giving fat 
 jobs to favorite contractors, and to provide fine drives for the 
 pleasure and convenience of others than the abutting property 
 owners " * * 
 
 On the whole, however, the special assessment has been an 
 unusual success as a fiscal expedient, and has proved an im- 
 portant, if not an indispensable, factor in the development of 
 American cities. Where its use has been followed by extrava- 
 gance, speculation, or jobbery, these evils are to be attributed almost 
 wholly to political corruption of the government, and only in a 
 very small measure to the special assessment itself. Most of the 
 evils, moreover, have arisen where the city government, or some 
 department of the city government like that of public works, has 
 been given the power to order the improvements against the will 
 of the property owners involved; or where as was the case in 
 the example cited above assessments upon particular lots were 
 permitted to exceed the value of the property. Special assess- 
 ments should not be levied against the will of a majority of the 
 property holders subject to assessment, except by a two thirds 
 or three fourths vote of the city council, and in no case should 
 the assessment exceed a small fraction of the value of the property 
 against which the assessment is laid. Where these rules are 
 observed, the special assessment is unlikely to lead either to pre- 
 mature development or hardship upon the property holder. 
 
 Taxes. More than 70 per cent of all the public revenues, 
 
 and nearly 95 per cent of the regular derivative revenues, are 
 
 obtained from taxes, so the problems of taxation are the most 
 
 important with which the public financier has to deal. These 
 
 1 Rosewater, Special Assessments: a Study in Municipal Finance.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 
 
 8. 
 
 & 2 
 
 o 2 
 
 H ^ 
 
 ^ Q 
 
 s s 
 
 x s 
 
 < H 
 
 h U 
 
 i 
 
 S 
 
 
 
 i/-, 
 
 IO 1-1 
 
 OO 
 
 PI 
 
 -r 
 
 
 n 
 
 PO 
 
 M 
 
 oo 
 i^ 
 
 >0 PI 
 PO PI 
 
 8 
 
 u 
 
 * 
 
 < M 
 
 Pi 
 
 
 
 
 ON IO 
 M M 
 
 T 
 
 
 * 
 
 M 
 
 PO 
 
 M 
 
 8 
 
 o *< 
 u 
 
 O 
 
 U-, 
 
 10 
 
 S cT 
 
 ~ 
 
 
 8 
 
 C 
 X 
 
 O\ 
 
 OO O 
 TT PI 
 
 o 
 
 cj 
 
 M 
 
 oe 
 
 ^ 
 
 00 
 
 '"i 
 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 ^O 
 
 O H 
 
 Os 
 
 j^ 
 
 c> 
 
 t> r\ 
 
 Q 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 "* 
 
 ~ f>> 
 
 ^3* 
 
 < 5 
 
 j^ 
 
 r< 
 
 
 
 o 2 
 
 js 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 'X 
 
 t 
 
 ^t oo 
 
 M 
 
 B 
 
 !" 
 
 O 
 
 N 
 
 PO 00 
 
 o 
 
 
 r*~. 
 
 Ifl 
 
 PI 
 
 00 f 
 
 Oj 
 
 3 
 
 1 
 
 $ 
 
 M 
 
 IO O 
 
 OO PO 
 
 -c 
 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 - 
 
 to 
 
 O 
 
 M 
 
 to 
 
 t 
 
 M 
 
 > in 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 8 
 
 >/-, 
 
 8 
 
 
 H 
 
 o 
 
 M 
 
 U o 
 
 PI 
 
 M 
 
 dv 
 
 S 
 
 
 :> 
 
 CI* 
 
 
 
 'X 
 
 to 
 
 o" 
 
 10 
 
 <*; 
 O0~ 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 p 
 
 n 
 
 
 
 
 w > 
 
 t 
 
 M 
 
 2 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 ~~^ 
 
 PI 
 
 Ov 
 
 M 
 
 I 5 
 
 X 
 
 * 
 
 oo 
 
 M 
 
 
 10 
 
 - 
 
 
 M 
 
 ir. 
 
 ^ 
 
 M 
 
 00~ 
 00 
 M 
 
 o 
 
 *" H Z H 
 
 8 
 
 r- 
 
 3D 
 
 X 
 
 
 | 
 
 oc 
 
 
 l ^' 
 
 'Z 
 
 O 
 
 00 
 
 00 
 | 
 
 * 1 
 
 00_ 
 
 <N 
 
 q~ 
 
 p" 
 Tt 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 M 
 IA 
 
 6 
 tn 
 
 00" 
 
 o" 
 
 
 u g B 
 
 hH 
 
 to 
 
 PO 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 , 
 
 w 
 
 n 
 
 B 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 O 
 
 k, 8 " 
 
 NO" 
 
 DC 
 
 L/~, 
 
 CC 
 X 
 
 
 1C 
 
 
 S 
 
 Z 
 
 PO 
 
 *^ 
 
 w 
 
 5 5 5 
 
 * 
 
 vO 
 
 
 
 c 7 
 
 
 "^ 
 
 
 H 
 
 *0 
 
 PO 
 
 2 h 
 
 PO 
 
 
 
 'O 
 
 
 
 
 
 N^ 
 
 ^ 
 
 f>M 
 
 IO 
 
 ON 
 
 
 
 CC 
 
 
 
 r- 
 
 
 U', 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 & a/ 9 
 
 *^> 
 
 
 CC 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 M 
 
 o- 
 
 9. 
 
 oO 
 
 PO 
 
 ll 
 
 oo" 
 
 9 
 
 ^ 
 
 o" 
 
 >- 
 
 
 Pi 
 
 
 ** 
 
 
 
 IO 
 
 to 
 
 i 
 
 00 
 
 8 
 
 
 1r 
 
 
 10 
 
 C 
 
 
 ~* 
 
 H 
 
 X 
 
 c-^ 
 
 00 
 PI 
 
 IO 
 
 J 
 
 to 
 
 H 
 
 ^^ 
 
 
 ~ 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 f^. 
 
 r-r 
 
 to 
 
 ^ 
 
 M 
 
 5 
 
 00 
 
 
 ^T 
 
 
 c 
 
 
 
 
 aa 
 
 M 
 
 J> 
 
 PO 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 
 ^. 
 
 
 ''Is 
 
 
 Cl 
 
 r 7' 
 
 ^ 
 
 *i 
 
 ^r 
 
 u 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 -r 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 J^ 
 
 o 
 
 5o 
 
 M 
 WJ 
 
 '^ 
 
 O 
 
 
 Tj- 
 1*1 
 
 
 M 
 f. 
 
 o_ 
 
 00 
 
 o 
 
 ^ 
 
 < i 
 
 e> 
 
 OC_ 
 
 10 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 to 
 
 t^ 
 
 PI 
 
 
 00 
 
 "5- 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 R 
 
 
 CC 
 
 M 
 
 JJ. 
 
 ^ 
 
 M 
 
 to 
 
 t ^ 
 
 PI 
 
 r-^. 
 
 r* 
 
 
 f"; 
 
 
 M 
 
 C4 
 
 t^. 
 
 00 
 
 PI 
 
 S H 
 e/5 (-1 
 
 * 
 
 PO 
 
 tP, 
 uo 
 
 
 00 
 
 
 (N 
 10 
 
 r* 
 
 ON 
 
 oo" 
 
 to 
 
 M 
 
 J W 
 
 00 
 
 
 M 
 
 00 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 . : R 
 
 N? 
 
 1 1 
 
 00 
 
 
 LT. 
 
 t^ o" 
 
 10 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 IO 
 
 H U 
 
 
 
 T 
 
 PO 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 o^ 
 
 !7 o 
 
 .- 
 
 
 GV 
 
 IO O 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ro 
 
 "T 
 
 5 
 
 ^^ 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 PI 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 W~, 
 
 PI PI 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 t; 
 
 
 
 (- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ri 
 
 
 
 
 
 rt x 
 
 a 
 
 
 
 J/j 
 
 
 v 
 
 i' 
 
 >. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 a 
 
 
 ; 3 
 
 1 
 
 1. 
 
 
 
 a\ QJ 
 en in 
 
 C C 
 
 : 3 
 
 & i 
 
 
 
 'f~ 
 
 
 ' cu 
 
 u 
 
 P 
 
 -r 
 
 
 U V 
 
 * W 
 
 C/3 [/j 
 
 
 
 r 
 
 
 hi 
 
 
 
 ^. 
 
 | 
 
 
 y .y 
 
 2 c 
 
 - ?* 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 V 
 
 
 
 
 r 
 
 
 
 d 
 
 
 I c 
 
 u 
 
 ^ 
 
 '7: 
 
 
 13 u 
 
 11 
 
 i; -* 
 
 
 en 
 
 | 
 
 i 
 
 "Si fe 
 
 J 
 
 'u 
 I; 
 
 ^ 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 ~ 
 3 
 
 j W 
 
 B, J 
 
 i 
 
 
 
 T! v 
 
 2 en 
 
 O 
 
 
 ft, 
 
 ^" 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 h
 
 6l2 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 problems are of two varieties; those dealing with the nature of 
 taxation in general, and those dealing with specific taxes. The 
 remainder of this chapter will be devoted to the general questions. 
 Chapter XXXV will be given over to the more specific problems 
 of American taxation. 
 
 Justice in Taxation. By far the most important lesson which 
 the student of fiscal questions has to learn is the supreme necessity 
 for tolerance and breadth of view. The factors which condition 
 justice or make for equity in taxation are exceedingly numerous; 
 and the mistake most commonly made by superficial thinkers is 
 to seize upon some one element of justice, build a philosophy upon 
 that alone, and vigorously condemn everything that does not 
 harmonize with their petty and bigoted little system. No maxim 
 less comprehensive than the greatest good of the greatest number, 
 and no rule less sweeping than that of the general welfare, can 
 serve as a safe guide for the financier. 
 
 1. Some writers go so far as wholly to deny the right of the 
 State to take private property by taxation. These writers forget 
 that there is no such thing as absolutely private property. As 
 the State determines what shall be private property, so also it 
 determines the conditions of its existence, and the most funda- 
 mental condition of private property is the obligation to con- 
 tribute to the support of the State. The rights of private in- 
 dividuals have always been of a more or less limited nature, and 
 among the rights reserved by the people in their organic capacity 
 will be found, in every civilized state, the right to take a portion 
 of the wealth produced for such purposes as the law-making 
 power may deem fit. 
 
 2. However, the State must exercise this power over private 
 property in an equitable manner, or as this maxim is ordinarily 
 expressed in the terminology of constitutional law, taxation must 
 be equal and uniform. Thus, for example, Section i, Article 10 
 of the Constitution of West Virginia provides that: "taxation 
 shall be equal and uniform throughout this state, and all property, 
 real and personal, shall be taxed in proportion to its value, to be 
 ascertained as directed by law." Now, if we examine the way 
 in which these requirements of equality and uniformity have
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 613 
 
 been interpreted in the administration of practical justice 
 and it is the kind of justice that will stand the wear and tear of 
 practical application with which we are concerned we find 
 that equality and uniformity have come to mean little more than 
 this, that taxation shall not be arbitrary, capricious, or plainly 
 unreasonable and that within each class of persons or object the 
 burden shall be equal, (a) Everywhere the legislature is given 
 a wide latitude in exempting property, so that institutions and 
 industries which are regarded as of peculiar value to the people 
 may be encouraged by freedom from taxation. Almost every- 
 where, poll taxes which impose an unequal burden upon the 
 poor, liquor licenses which impose unequal obligations upon the 
 saloon, inheritance and corporation taxes which single out partic- 
 ular classes of society for unusual taxation, are sustained by the 
 courts. Justice in taxation, then, does not require rigid equality or 
 narrow uniformity of treatment, (b) Institutions which are socially 
 harmful may be subject to peculiarly drastic and oppressive 
 taxation; that is to say, justice may take into account sumptuary 
 considerations, (c] Old taxes, which would not be used if they 
 were not already intrenched in the fiscal and social system, are 
 permitted to endure; justice takes cognizance of the fact that, other 
 things being equal, an old tax is a good tax by very reason of its 
 age. (d) Indirect taxes which weigh more heavily upon the poor 
 than the rich show no signs of disappearing; that is to say, 
 justice gives due weight to the productivity of a tax, its cheapness 
 of collection, and convenience of payment, and balances these con- 
 siderations against factors which we are accustomed to regard as 
 more fundamentally ethical, (e) Taxes may be employed to sup- 
 press state banks of issue, protect home manufactures, and in 
 general to accomplish political and social ends other than the 
 mere raising of revenue. Taxation is seldom the best agent of 
 social or political reform. If there is an evil which needs eradica- 
 tion, the best way is to suppress it directly, if possible, rather than 
 discourage it a little by general taxation. But this does not affect 
 the general proposition that where taxation is an efficient remedy, 
 or the only remedy, justice sanctions its employment. (/) Finally, 
 it is plain that, however we strive, nothing better than approxi-
 
 614 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 mate justice can ever be secured in taxation. A system that 
 frankly recognizes this truth and makes for rough justice, by the 
 imposition of taxes which are simple, stable, convenient, inex- 
 pensive and productive, is far better than one which attempts to 
 secure exact justice through complex and delicate schemes of 
 taxation which cannot be definitely or efficiently administered. 
 
 3. The theory of justice most widely accepted by American 
 courts at the present time is expressed in the maxim that taxes 
 should be proportioned to benefits derived. Like other rules of 
 justice, this maxim contains elements of truth and elements of 
 error. It is a fairly helpful guide, for instance, in dealing with 
 public revenues other than taxes. Public prices, fees, and special 
 assessments should, as we have seen, be proportioned to benefits, 
 unless there is strong reason for departing from the rule. And 
 in the apportionment of taxation among districts or govern- 
 mental sections, the rule still retains, and probably always will 
 retain, a large measure of validity. Taxation, we say, must per- 
 tain to the district taxed, meaning by this that under ordinary 
 circumstances it is not wise to tax District A for the benefit of 
 District B; although there are important exceptions to this rule. 
 But in the apportionment of taxes among the individuals of a given 
 district, the rule has little or no place. This conclusion follows, 
 if for no other reason, from our definition of the word "taxes," 
 which we confine to contributions levied without reference to 
 special benefits received, either because no special benefit can be 
 assigned, or because (as in the case of free schools) we specifically 
 desire to lift the cost of the service from the shoulders of some of 
 those who specially benefit by the service. Moreover, in general, 
 it is impracticable to determine what proportion of the general 
 benefits of government accrue to particular individuals. 
 
 4. At the present time a great majority of economists agree 
 that taxes should be apportioned according to "faculty" or ability 
 to pay. It must be confessed that the rule is not very satisfactory. 
 For example, the faculty principle fails to explain such a generally 
 satisfactory tax as the inheritance tax, 1 which is sometimes ad- 
 
 1 The attempt is often made to justify the inheritance tax by the ability theory, 
 but unsuccessfully. See West, The Inheritance Tax, (Revised Edition), pp. 205- 
 208.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 615 
 
 justed to the size of the inheritance and the relationship of the 
 heir, and sometimes to the size of the estate from which the in- 
 heritance is taken, but never to the total property, income, or 
 general ability of the recipient. Moreover, the ability principle 
 is not very precise. No simple measure of ability exists, and 
 many taxes, which under a superficial examination seem to con- 
 form to the rule, such as the general property or income tax, are 
 found upon closer examination to violate the rule in a thousand 
 ways. Despite all these defects, however, the ability principle 
 has elements of great strength. It satisfies our sense of justice, 
 in the first place, when explicit reasons cannot be given for de- 
 parting from a general rule; and it expresses the ideal towards 
 which we strive in voluntary contributions to the church or other 
 voluntary joint enterprises of a social nature. In the second 
 place, we can frequently ascertain with certainty that the rule 
 is being violated, when we cannot define its meaning positively, 
 and hence it is capable of practical application in a negative way. 
 We may therefore accept the rule in this sense, that unless other 
 treatment is justified by the considerations cited in paragraph 2, 
 above, or by analogous reasons, no tax which is plainly dispro- 
 portional to the ability of the contributors, should be employed. 
 5. Accepting the ability principle as the best simple rule for 
 general taxes as distinguished from the specific taxes noted in para- 
 graph 2, we at once encounter the difficult question, how is ability 
 to be measured ? Different writers have recommended as the basis 
 or measure of ability, income, outgo or consumption, and property. 
 A little consideration will convince the reader that each of these 
 measures is marked by minor defects. The consumption of the 
 poor, for instance, is out of all proportion to their ability to bear 
 the burdens of the state. Property, on the other hand, differs 
 widely in its productiveness, and, moreover, many persons with 
 a little property have large incomes, and therefore great ability 
 to bear taxation. Incomes, similarly, differ in permanence and 
 security, and equal incomes are called upon to support very un- 
 equal numbers of persons. Fortunately, it is not imperative in 
 practice to make a decision between these measures of ability. 
 The necessities of fiscal administration make it imperative in
 
 616 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 actual practice to employ all three bases of taxation. Property, 
 consumption, and income are all employed in the United States 
 at the present time and will unquestionably continue to be em- 
 ployed for many generations. 
 
 Progressive Taxation. After we adopt any concrete measure 
 of ability, we soon realize that it is only approximately correct, 
 because we are immediately confronted with the question: Does 
 ability increase in direct proportion or more rapidly than our 
 measure of ability; in other words, shall taxes be laid in direct 
 proportion to income, property, etc., or shall the rate be increased 
 as the amount of income or property increases ? The first method 
 is called proportional taxation, the second progressive or graduated. 
 If the rate diminishes as the income or property increases, we 
 speak of it as regressive taxation; and if the rate increases faster 
 than the income or property, but toward a fixed limit which it 
 can never exceed, it is referred to as degressive taxation. 1 The 
 last kind of rating is of course a special variety of progressive 
 taxation, and usually results from the combination of a nominally 
 proportional rate with the exemption of a fixed sum from all in- 
 comes or assessed wealth. The American property tax is theo- 
 retically a degressive tax, though it is regressive in practical effect. 
 
 From the theoretical standpoint our real knowledge upon this 
 subject is exceedingly unsatisfactory. On the whole, the argu- 
 ments of those who approve progressive taxation are more con- 
 vincing than those of its opponents, and a majority of economists 
 at the present time agree in asserting that ability increases faster 
 than income, property, or any common measure of ability. If 
 we construe ability as ability to bear sacrifice (as John Stuart 
 Mill and some other authorities do) and confine our attention 
 solely to the consumer, there can be no doubt that progressive 
 taxation is the means by which the least sacrifice will be visited 
 upon the community as a whole. 2 This is a strong argument 
 because one of the chief immediate effects of taxation is to deprive 
 
 1 The income tax of Hesse, German}', begins at .6 per cent on small incomes 
 and approaches, but never quite reaches, 5 per cent, as the incomes become very 
 large. 
 
 2 See Carver, "Ethical Basis of Distribution," Annals of the American Academy 
 of Political and Social Science, Vol. VI, pp. 79-99.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 617 
 
 persons of the necessaries, conveniences, and luxuries of life, 
 while the maxim of the greatest good to the greatest number - 
 or as it works out in taxation, the least sacrifice to the least num- 
 ber is one of the most widely accepted rules of social conduct. 
 Surveying the ability theory from the positive standpoint of 
 ability to acquire or produce property, we find the testimony 
 almost universal, that as the fortune or income increases, the ability 
 to earn or produce more increases at an accelerating pace. "It 
 is the first thousand that counts," in the language of the successful 
 man who is telling the younger generation how he succeeded. 
 
 Coming to the more concrete and more practical arguments, 
 we find that the balance of opinion also inclines to the side of those 
 who favor progressive taxation. Let us briefly recapitulate these 
 arguments and attempt to estimate their net resultant. Those 
 who oppose progressive taxation charge that the proposal is 
 socialistic, that it would discourage the accumulation of wealth, 
 that it would not be particularly productive, meaning by this 
 that the element of progressivity adds little to what would be 
 produced by a proportional rate, that it would stimulate fraud 
 and evasion, that it would interfere with the device known as 
 "collection at the source," and that finally the whole principle is 
 arbitrary and capricious in the sense that there is no natural limit 
 to the increase of the rate. 
 
 To these charges the defendants of progressive taxation present 
 plans 1 by which collection at the source and progressive rating 
 may be successfully combined in the same system; and reply, 
 further, that terms are immaterial and questions cannot be settled 
 by bandying epithets such as "socialistic," "anarchistic," and the 
 like; that every tax discourages the accumulation of wealth; 
 that whether the tax will be productive or not, it will relieve the 
 poorer classes to the extent that the progressive rates do actually 
 fall upon the rich; that persons capable of evading their obliga- 
 tions to the government will attempt to evade proportional taxes 
 as well as progressive taxes; and that all taxation is more or less 
 arbitrary, resting upon the judgment and common sense of the 
 
 1 Report from the Select [British] Committee on Income Tax, 1906 [365], 
 pp. iii-vii.
 
 618 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 legislature. The exemptions made in every tax law, the size of 
 license fees of all kinds, the rates of excise and customs duties, 
 are all "arbitrary" and unlimited in the sense that progressive 
 taxation is arbitrary and unlimited. Finally, the defendant of 
 progressive taxation points out that, owing to the great prominence 
 of indirect taxes in our revenue system and the tendency of as- 
 sessors to assess large properties at a lower proportion of real 
 value than smaller properties, American taxation to-day is in 
 practice regressive, and some progressivity is needed, if only to 
 balance the admitted regressivity of existing taxes. 
 
 While general considerations thus seem to warrant a most 
 persistent effort to introduce a moderate measure of progress- 
 ivity into our direct taxes, the student is warned that this should 
 not be done in any doctrinaire or off-hand fashion. A thousand 
 considerations of practical expediency must be taken into account 
 in the shaping of a revenue system, and in the end we are more 
 likely to attain the goal which the advocates of progressive taxa- 
 tion seek by careful exemptions from taxation, by special taxes 
 upon corporations, monopolies, inheritances, and certain forms 
 of income, and by directing expenditures to the succor of the weak 
 and the equalization of opportunity, than by the introduction of 
 any far-reaching single tax such as a progressive income or prop- 
 erty tax. 
 
 No tax system, then, can be fairly judged without reference 
 to the character of expenditures. Where the expenditures are 
 wasteful, corrupt, and unwise, heavy taxation is a curse, although 
 even here the rational method of reform is rather to root out the 
 corruption and improve the administration, than to reduce taxa- 
 tion, although temporarily it may be wise to do the latter. But 
 where the expenditures are on the whole wisely and beneficently 
 used, heavy taxation is a blessing. No country was ever yet 
 ruined by large expenditures of money by the public and for the 
 public. The true theory to be observed in levying taxes was 
 tersely expressed in the 4ist section of the constitution adopted by 
 Pennsylvania in 1776: "No public tax, custom or contribution 
 shall be imposed upon, or paid by, the people of this state, except 
 by a law for that purpose; and before any law be made for raising
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 619 
 
 it, the purpose for which any tax is to be raised ought to appear 
 clearly to the legislature to be of more service to the community 
 than the money would be if not collected, which being well ob- 
 served, taxes can never be burthens." 
 
 The Shifting of Taxes. Up to this point we have been speak- 
 ing as if a tax must remain where it is originally placed. This 
 we know is not always the case. Excise taxes, for instance, are 
 usually levied with the expectation that they will be passed or 
 shifted from the business man, who first pays them, to the con- 
 sumer or some other person. The conditions which control the 
 shifting of taxes must evidently be considered at least in a very 
 general way before we discuss the practical working of the 
 American system of taxations. 
 
 The word "shifting" usually refers to the increase of price by 
 which the original payer of the tax attempts to recoup himself. 
 This increase of price is usually accompanied by collateral economic 
 disturbances or dislocations suggested by the phrase "re- 
 percussion of taxes" which is frequently employed in this con- 
 nection that are quite as important as the mere change in price. 
 For instance, an excise tax (per unit of product) upon a monopoly 
 may raise the price by as much or even more than the tax itself. 
 But the monopolist nevertheless feels the burden of the tax in 
 reduced profits. When we say that a tax is shifted, then, we do 
 not imply that the original payer evades all the evil effects of the 
 tax. And in any conclusive discussion of shifting, account should 
 be taken of the incidence or benefit of governmental expenditures. 
 A tax system which bears heavily upon the poor may be justified 
 by expenditures which are largely employed to educate and pro- 
 vide opportunities for the poor. 
 
 Mobility is the chief factor which controls shifting; and this 
 in turn is largely dependent upon the generality or scope of the 
 tax, and upon the existence of monopoly or differential advan- 
 tages. Place a tax upon a person or thing which can easily 
 move to a jurisdiction where such taxes are not imposed, and 
 the tax is very likely to be shifted. Local taxes upon mortgage 
 loans offer a good example. Such taxes are very likely to raise 
 the interest rate by as much or a little more than the tax rate,
 
 620 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the "little more" being explained by the trouble imposed upon 
 the lender in looking after the tax and the risk that the tax rate 
 will be increased. On the other hand, if mortgage lenders are 
 constrained by ignorance or custom or the existence of particu- 
 larly high rates in this district to keep on supplying the old amounts 
 of loans, the tax will not be shifted. Unless the supply can be 
 or is reduced by the tax, shifting will not ordinarily take place. 
 
 Naturally, therefore, the particular nature of the supply is of 
 prime importance. We may illustrate by an excise tax per unit 
 of product upon competitive industries of various kinds. In 
 industries subject to the law of constant expense, a fixed tax per 
 unit of product will raise the price by just the amount of the tax, 
 in theory. In industries subject to the law of increasing expense, 
 however, the reduction of the supply caused by the tax somewhat 
 reduces the expenses of production per unit exclusive of the tax, 
 and on this account prices in such industries will increase by 
 an amount less than the tax. In industries subject to the law of 
 diminishing expense, on the other hand, the price will be raised 
 by an amount equal to the tax, plus an amount equal to the in- 
 creased expense of production caused by the limitation of supply. 
 
 Mobility, as has been said, is the most important factor in this 
 connection, and it may be restricted or destroyed in a variety 
 of ways. Monopoly limits mobility, and, as we have seen in 
 Chapter XIII, 1 the monopolist cannot shift a fixed tax or a propor- 
 tional tax on net profits unless the tax is so high as to reduce 
 monopoly profits below the amount that could be earned on the 
 same investment in a competitive industry. For somewhat 
 similar, but not exactly the same reasons, differential gains from 
 durable property are peculiarly susceptible to taxation. Thus, 
 economists generally indorse the proposition that a tax on economic 
 rent falls upon the landlord and cannot be shifted. The validity 
 of this depends both upon the durability of land and the fact that 
 the tax is levied upon a differential element. If land wore out 
 and had to be replenished, the tax would reduce the future sup- 
 ply of land and hence raise its price and its rent in the future. 
 Similarly, if the tax were levied upon the product of marginal or 
 
 1 pp. 200, aor.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 621 
 
 no-rent land, it would elevate the margin, reduce the supply of 
 those products or services which land affords, and in this way 
 again raise prices and partially reimburse the landlord. But, 
 by hypothesis, neither of these suppositions are true. Land, 
 as we define it, does not wear out; and at the margin land yields 
 no economic rent. 
 
 The proposition that a tax on economic rent cannot be shifted 
 is true, also, only of a proportional tax. A tax of so much per 
 bushel or pound upon agricultural produce would move the 
 margin of cultivation and thus affect prices. Indeed, the exact 
 form of a tax whether fixed, proportional, or progressive, upon 
 net or gross returns, upon product or upon profit is of funda- 
 mental importance always. Generally speaking, proportional taxes 
 upon net income are less easily shifted than other forms of taxes. 
 
 If the object of taxation be durable and the tax a special or 
 exclusive one, the value of the object is likely to be reduced by 
 the capitalized value of the tax. Prospective purchasers of land, 
 for instance, always take into account the taxes that are likely 
 to be levied upon it, capitalize these, and subtract their capitalized 
 value from the amount which they would pay for the property 
 if it were not liable to taxation. The apparent result of this 
 capitalization or amortization of taxes, as the process is called, is to 
 place the burden of an endless succession of taxes upon the original 
 owner, and relieve subsequent purchasers of any real burden. 
 
 Many present-day followers of Henry George find in this prin- 
 ciple of 'amortization at once a justification and a method of 
 securing for society all economic rent. Under present conditions, 
 they say, a man who buys land wholly escapes taxation upon it. 
 Consequently, in order to make landowners pay as much as other 
 people we should have to increase the tax upon land by a rate 
 equal to that paid by the average tax-payer as often say every 
 thirty years as the land of the community changes holders. 
 In this way the State could gradually and with justice absorb all 
 economic rent. 1 
 
 1 Sec the paper upon "The Single Tax" by C. B. Fillebrown in State and Local 
 Taxation (the Addresses and Proceedings of the First National Conference of the 
 National Tax Association), pp. 286-293.
 
 622 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 But this whole chain of reasoning is fallacious for three reasons: 
 (a) This capitalization takes place only to the extent that the 
 tax on land is exclusive and unequal, and modern taxes upon land 
 are not of this nature. (6) In so far as this programme of the 
 single taxers were anticipated and understood, it would 
 visit the whole burden of the "reform" upon present owners, 
 instead of being distributed over several generations. Sub- 
 sequent purchasers would discount these periodic increases of the 
 tax and pay to owners for their land only the present value of 
 the rapidly vanishing income from land. Land would be valued 
 simply as a terminable annuity, (c) This whole doctrine over- 
 looks the inevitable consequence that, if "the selling value of 
 land is an untaxed value" l and if "the burden of a land tax can- 
 not be made to survive a change of ownership," 2 these facts would 
 so increase the demand for land that the profits from its purchase 
 and ownership would not exceed profits in other lines of invest- 
 ment. Given plenty of time, active competition, together with 
 a knowledge of the facts of the situation, and such inequalities 
 of taxation are inevitably smoothed out by the natural movement 
 of capital toward the taxless field or away from the field in which 
 burdens are particularly severe. 
 
 This inevitable reckoning of taxation among the disadvantages 
 of industry, brings it to pass that many old taxes are diffused over 
 the entire community. Such diffusion does not take place when 
 the nature of the supply prevents it from varying in nice cor- 
 respondence with the prospects of profit. A poll tax upon laborers, 
 for instance, will in our opinion not be shifted, as it is likely to 
 lower their standard of living, stimulate the birth rate, and in turn 
 (other things being equal) actually reduce wages. But exclusive 
 taxes on capital and business will be diffused; and for this reason 
 there is a profound practical truth in the famous dictum of Canard 
 that "every old tax is good; every new tax is bad," when sympa- 
 thetically interpreted. Of course this doctrine assumes that in- 
 dustrial changes are infrequent. The tax system must and should 
 
 1 See the paper upon " The Single Tax " by C. B. Fillebrown in State and Local 
 Taxation (the Addresses and Proceedings of the First National Conference of the 
 National Tax Association), p. 290. * Ibid., p. 290.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 623 
 
 vary with changes in the fortunes of business enterprise. The 
 development of a new industry making unusual and unexpected 
 profits offers a good opportunity of relieving an old industry that 
 has unexpectedly fallen upon evil days. And for this reason it 
 is highly desirable that state constitutions prescribing a rigidly 
 uniform system of taxation should be amended so as to permit 
 reasonable classification of property and business for purposes 
 of taxation. All these qualifications of the diffusion theory are 
 true and important. But the fact still remains that under ordinary 
 conditions nothing is worse in a tax system than uncertainty, 
 continual tinkering with rates, and capricious readjustment of 
 methods. 
 
 QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 
 
 1. In accordance with what principles of classification do we distinguish 
 fees, special assessments, and taxes? 
 
 2. Enumerate six distinct fees commonly employed by state governments. 
 
 3. Can a fee exceed the cost of the service to the state? Is the familiar 
 "high liquor license" a fee or a tax? 
 
 4. What accounts for the rapid development of the special assessment in 
 the last fifty years? Is it possible to apportion the benefits of a public im- 
 provement with any degree of accuracy? 
 
 5. Make a table from the Census Volume on Wealth, Debt, and Taxa- 
 tion, showing the relative importance in each governmental division, of the 
 taxes differentiated in Table I. 
 
 6. Why are liquor licenses distinguished from other licenses and permits? 
 
 7. Has the state a greater right to tax land and natural agents than 
 wealth which is, in large degree, a product of human labor? 
 
 8. May monopolies be equitably subjected to special taxation ? Even 
 if the monopoly rests upon superior efficiency, or upon patent rights justly 
 acquired ? 
 
 9. Is rigid equality of taxation a primary and fundamental desideratum? 
 Is it possible of achievement? Is there any real distinction between the 
 so-called ethical qualities (of equality, uniformity, etc.) and the so-called ad- 
 ministrative qualities (convenience, elasticity, productivity, etc.) of a tax? 
 
 10. Is the benefit principle wrong or merely impossible of application? 
 If wrong, why do we retain it in fees and special assessments? 
 
 n. Is it easier to measure ability than benefits? 
 
 12. Is progressive taxation arbitrary ? Can it be satisfactorily considered 
 apart from the effect of public expenditures ? 
 
 13. Work out the effect of an excise tax on a monopoly subject to the law 
 of increasing cost.
 
 624 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BASTABLE, D. F. Public Finance, Book III, Chap. Ill, "The Distribution 
 
 of Taxation," pp. 281-315; Chap. V, "The Shifting and Incidence of 
 
 Taxation," pp. 337-362; Chap. VII, "The Canons of Taxation," 
 
 pp. 382-391. 
 CARVER, T. N. "Ethical Basis of Distribution," Annals of the American 
 
 Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. VI, pp. 79-99. 
 COOLEY, T. M. A Treatise on the Law of Taxation (3d ed.), Chap. II, 
 
 "The Nature of the Power to Tax," pp. 43-82; Chap. VI, "Equality 
 
 and Uniformity in Taxation," pp. 254-410. 
 CROWELL, T. Y. & Co. (Pub.). Equitable Taxation, Essay by W. E. Weyl, 
 
 pp. 17-31. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Taxation in American States and Cities, Part I, Chap. III. 
 GRAY, J. M. Limitation of Taxing Power on Public Indebtedness, 
 
 "Equality and Uniformity," Chaps. XVIII-XXIV, pp. 642-915; 
 
 "The Origin and Growth of Modern Taxation," pp. 25-54. 
 JUDSON, F. N. A Treatise on the Pou'er of Taxation, passim. 
 ROSEWATER, VICTOR. Special Assessments: a Study in Municipal Finance, 
 
 passim. Studies in History, Economics, and Public Law, Columbia 
 
 University, Vol II, No. 3. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. The Shifting and Incidence of Taxation, Part II, 
 
 Chap. I, "General Principles," pp. 179-219. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, Part II, 
 
 Chap. IV, "Conclusion," pp. 190-200; Part III, "Application of the 
 
 Progressive Principle to American Taxation." pp. 201-217. 
 National Tax Association. State and Local Taxation [Addresses and Proceed- 
 ings of the First National Conference]. 
 URDAHL, T. K. The Fee System in the United States, Chap I, pp. 49-67; 
 
 Chap. VIII, pp. 210-230. Transactions of the Wisconsin Academy of 
 
 Science, Arts, and Letters, Vol. XII, Part I. 
 WESTON, S. F. Principles of Justice in Taxation, passim. Studies in 
 
 History, Economics, and Public Law, Columbia University, Vol. 17, 
 
 No. a.
 
 CHAPTER XXXV 
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES; FEDERAL, STATE, AND LOCAL 
 TAXES 
 
 FEDERAL TAXATION 
 
 Direct and Indirect Taxes. The fundamental character of the 
 American revenue system is determined by those clauses of the 
 federal Constitution which provide that "direct taxes shall be 
 apportioned among the several states . . . according to their 
 respective numbers"; that "all duties, imposts, and excises shall 
 be uniform throughout the United States"; and that "no state 
 shall, without the consent of Congress, levy any imposts or duties 
 on imports or exports, except what may be absolutely necessary 
 for executing its inspection laws." 
 
 Just what the words duties, imposts, excises, direct and in- 
 direct taxes signify, as used in the Constitution, has been a matter 
 of considerable discussion. Ordinarily the word duty "means an 
 indirect tax imposed upon the importation, exportation, or con- 
 sumption of goods," being given "a broader meaning than cus- 
 tom, which is a duty imposed upon imports or exports," while 
 "the term impost also signifies any tax, tribute, or duty, but it 
 seldom applied to any but indirect taxes. An excise duty is an 
 inland impost levied upon articles of manufacture or sale, and 
 also upon licenses to pursue certain trades or to deal in certain 
 commodities." 
 
 But all these definitions are made to hinge upon the meaning 
 of direct and indirect taxes, and that meaning is exceedingly 
 doubtful. Until 1894, it was believed by most persons that as 
 used in the Constitution of the United States, these terms were 
 to be given an historical interpretation, to be accepted as used 
 in 1789, and that in this interpretation capitation and land taxes 
 
 2S 625
 
 626 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 were probably the only forms of direct taxes. This belief was 
 sustained by the fact that the Federal Supreme Court at various 
 times sanctioned the employment by Congress of income, inherit- 
 ance, and special property or consumption taxes. But in the 
 income tax decision of 1894 the Supreme Court reversed its 
 earlier decisions, declared the income tax to be "direct," and 
 interpreted the words direct and indirect in accordance with the 
 economic rather than the historical or legal use of those terms. 
 According to most economists, direct taxes are taxes levied by the 
 State upon those who are expected to bear the burden of them, while 
 indirect taxes are supposed to be shifted to other persons. In the 
 economic sense, poll taxes, property, income, and inheritance 
 taxes are usually called direct, while customs taxes and excise 
 taxes are called indirect. 
 
 It is plain that the economic meaning of these words is exceed- 
 ingly vague, because it is made to turn upon the expectation of 
 the user concerning the shifting of the tax, and upon no subject 
 in the entire province of political economy is there more uncer- 
 tainty than upon the shifting of taxes. Because of this uncer- 
 tainty, economists have for years protested against the use of 
 these terms at all in scientific analysis, although they have tried 
 to introduce a more consistent usage, owing to their constant 
 employment in popular discussion. Under these circumstances, 
 it was exceedingly unfortunate that the Supreme Court turned 
 away from the legal interpretation of the words. When the 
 latter were placed in the Constitution, they probably had no defi- 
 nite or accepted meaning; they had no definite or accepted 
 meaning as used later by economists or publicists ; and the only 
 way they could attain precision was by legal interpretation. 
 After a number of consistent opinions which gave the words a 
 definite connotation and promised to clear up a difficult situa- 
 tion once for all, the Supreme Court threw everything into chaos 
 again by revising opinions which had stood unchanged for many 
 years. 
 
 Use of Direct Taxes by the Federal Government. The effect 
 of the constitutional provisions which we have been discussing 
 has been to concentrate federal taxation almost wholly upon con-
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 62; 
 
 sumption, since direct taxes when apportioned according to 
 population have shown themselves to be unjust, unproductive, 
 and exceedingly difficult of collection. Congress has made use 
 of direct taxes only five times during the history of the national 
 government. Two million dollars was apportioned in 1798; 
 $3,000,000 in 1813; $6,000,000 in 1815; $3,000,000 in 1816; 
 and $20,000,000 in 1861. Except in the tax of 1798, Congress 
 has always permitted any state to assume its quota and raise 
 the money as it saw fit, although provision was always made for 
 the collection of the amount usually by taxes on lands, houses, 
 and slaves by federal officers, in case the quota was not as- 
 sumed by the state government. It would be difficult to exag- 
 gerate the unsatisfactory character of such taxation. In no case 
 has the federal government ever collected the full amount of the 
 tax. The taxes levied in 1814-1816 continued to be collected 
 until 1839. The last payments on the direct tax of 1861 were 
 not received until 1888; and in 1891 a law was passed abolishing 
 further collections and authorizing the amounts which had been 
 collected under the act of 1861 to be returned. Considerable 
 scandal arose out of this refunding act owing to the enormous 
 commissions paid to certain lobbyists for their work at Washing- 
 ton in securing the passage of the law. Experience has thus 
 made it amply clear that the federal government must put its 
 dependence upon customs duties, excises, and similar taxes. 
 
 Customs Duties. Among federal revenues, customs duties 
 easily occupy the place of first importance. From the founda- 
 tion of the federal government in 1789 until the Civil War, with 
 the exception of a few excise taxes collected between 1791 and 
 1802, the federal government derived nearly all its permanent 
 regular revenues from customs taxation, and since the Civil War 
 considerably more than 50 per cent of the permanent revenue 
 has, on the average, been derived from this source. From the 
 very beginning, moreover, our customs duties have been in spirit, 
 if not in effect, protective; and it thus becomes necessary to 
 consider the connection between the protective and revenue 
 principles, in addition to the more strictly fiscal aspects of customs 
 duties.
 
 628 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Protective duties are imposed in the hope of diminishing im- 
 ports and substituting in their stead the products of home manu- 
 facturers. To the extent, therefore, that they are successful in 
 their purpose, they reduce the customs revenues and justify the 
 statement that there is a fundamental antagonism between the 
 protective and revenue principles. However, the reduction of 
 importation does not signify that the consumers of the article in 
 question are not taxed. So long as the price remains higher than 
 it would be if no duty were imposed, the people are taxed to the 
 extent of the difference, the proceeds of the tax going to home 
 manufacturers in the form of an unmeasured, unregulated bounty, 
 whose burden upon the taxpayers is no less real because unper- 
 ceived. 
 
 It is equally evident that no protection is given unless the price 
 is raised. The popularity of customs duties is largely explained 
 by the belief that the foreigner can be made to bear the burden 
 of the tax. He can in some cases, but not in the majority of 
 cases. For the most part it is believed that the burden must be 
 borne by the home consumer. But whatever the extent to which 
 the foreigner can be made to pay the tax, to that extent the tariff 
 fails to replace foreign by home products; in short, fails to "pro- 
 tect." We cannot save our cake and eat it. The more the 
 protection or bounty to the home manufacturers, the greater the 
 tax upon the consumers, the less the shifting of the tax to the 
 foreigner, and the less the revenue to the home government. 
 The protectionist is logically deprived of the time-worn argument 
 that the foreigner foots the bill. 
 
 The shifting of import duties may be best explained by noticing separately 
 the immediate and ultimate incidence, (i) The immediate effect of the tax 
 will be to discourage certain foreign producers from shipping their products 
 to the newly restricted market, and prices will tend to rise because of dimin- 
 ished supply. If the product is controlled by a foreign monopoly, the 
 price may not increase; but where the foreign production takes place under 
 competitive conditions, and in most cases where the production is monopo- 
 lized, the price will be raised. The increase of price may be more or less or 
 exactly equal to the tax according to the readiness with which foreign pro- 
 ducers find a new market, but in a large majority of cases the burden of 
 the tax will be shared by the producer and consumer, the latter according
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 629 
 
 to the majority of authorities bearing most of the burden. That the 
 burden, however, is partially borne by the foreign producer accords not only 
 with the best theory, but with the great interest displayed by exporters every- 
 where in the tariff legislation of foreign countries, and the sacrifices which 
 protectionist governments are willing to make in reciprocity treaties for the 
 purpose of obtaining advantageous terms for their own producers. 
 
 (2) Eventually, however, the initial increase in price may stimulate home 
 production, and this can only take place when the increase of price is less 
 than the duty, because if the price rises by the whole amount of the tax, the 
 foreigner will still possess his initial advantage. If the home producer totally 
 ousts the foreigner, then the consumer bears all the difference between the 
 existing price and the price that would rule if no duty were imposed 
 although, of course, the treasury receives nothing. If the home producer 
 secures only a part of the home market, it is plain that, under ordinary 
 circumstances, the foreigner pays part of the tax, i.e. the amount per unit 
 of product by which the duty exceeds the increase of price; whilst, as before, 
 the home consumer pays, on every unit consumed, a tax equal to the differ- 
 ence between the old and the new prices. When, however, we attempt to 
 go further and take account of the indirect effects of protection, the problem 
 becomes almost hopelessly complex. Modern economists, however, are 
 substantially agreed that the foreign producer bears a much larger share of 
 the average customs duty than the English economists of the first half of the 
 nineteenth century were willing to admit. 
 
 From the standpoint of revenue, American customs duties 
 have the great virtues of high productivity, convenience of pay- 
 ment, and cheapness of collection. Along with these important 
 virtues are associated almost all the vices to which indirect taxes 
 are subject, (a) The most important defects of our customs 
 taxes are their unreliability and uncertainty. Historically, they 
 have shown a pernicious variability, expanding when increased 
 revenue spelt extravagance, contracting when the country sorely 
 needed larger revenue. In 1791, for instance, the customs 
 revenue exceeded the total ordinary expenditures by over 41 per 
 cent, while in the very next year they fell short of the expenditures 
 by 58 per cent. Between 1791 and 1860 inclusive, the customs 
 receipts actually exceeded the expenditures in thirty-four years; 
 varied between 50 and 100 per cent of the expenditures in twenty- 
 eight years; and fell below 50 per cent in eight years. In 1860, 
 more than 84 per cent of the expenditures were secured from 
 this source, but in 1863 less than 10 per cent, so inadequate is
 
 630 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 the customs revenue in a serious war when money is most needed. 
 In 1864, Congress made desperate attempts to increase its cus- 
 toms revenue. In the tariff act of that year about fifteen hun- 
 dred articles were enumerated, and the average rate approxi- 
 mated 50 per cent; yet the receipts dropped from something 
 over one hundred and two millions in 1864 to less than eighty- 
 five millions in 1865, constituting only 6.5 per cent of the total 
 expenditures in the latter year. During the history of the national 
 government, the customs revenues have varied with the industrial 
 condition of the country, the prospects of peace or war, the power 
 of the tariff lobby, the prosperity and commercial policy of foreign 
 nations, but almost never in nice accordance with the financial 
 needs of the federal government. Where the tariff is controlled 
 by revenue rather than protective purposes, it can be made strik- 
 ingly stable and responsive to the control of the treasury. " The 
 English revenue from this source has kept very near ^20,000,000 
 per annum for the last thirty years. In the period 1815-1895, 
 it has only varied between ^24,000,000 and 1 9,000,000, not- 
 withstanding the extensive remissions of taxation." i 
 
 (b) From the fiscal standpoint, our tariff system is far too com- 
 plex and cumbersome. Whether we tax many imports or few, 
 the major part of the revenue comes from comparatively few 
 imports, so that by extending the list of dutiable articles we 
 merely add to the cost of collection and increase the interference 
 with commerce, without materially augmenting the yield of the 
 tax. Great Britain taxes less than fifty articles, and nearly all 
 of her revenue from import taxation comes from five articles, 
 tobacco, tea, spirits, wine, and sugar. Compared with direct 
 taxes the cost of collecting our import duties is not high (2.55 per 
 cent of the receipts in 1907), yet it exceeds the cost of collecting 
 the internal revenue duties (1.72 per cent in 1907); and in some 
 customs districts the expenses of collecting actually exceed the 
 tax collected. In fact, the administration of the entire system 
 is cumbersome, inquisitorial, and irritating. 
 
 "There is no better illustration of a complex and incomprehensible 
 revenue system than the tariff legislation of the United States. It levies 
 
 1 Bastable, Public Finance, p. 517 (written in 1895).
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 631 
 
 import duties upon goods that make up the country's exports as well as upon 
 those that constitute the normal imports of the nation's commerce; it taxes 
 raw material as well as the manufactured product, and the manufactured 
 product itself is taxed at many stages in the process of its manufacture; the 
 rate imposed is determined in part by considerations of revenue, in part by 
 the desire to grant 'incidental protection,' and in part for the purpose of 
 prohibiting the import of selected articles; the rules of rating are numerous, 
 overlapping each other in many cases and resulting in a confusion of instruc- 
 tions that necessitates a board of appeal in continuous session; the text of 
 the law makes a book of one hundred and fifty pages, while the law and its 
 interpretation used by the officials as a guide in the performance of their 
 duty is a volume of several hundred pages. A law of this sort cannot be 
 comprehended." l 
 
 Customs duties are either specific or ad valorem. Specific 
 duties are laid in proportion to weight or number, without regard 
 to value, while ad valorem duties are levied in proportion to the 
 value of the commodities imported. Ad valorem duties are open 
 to the objection that they offer a greater temptation to fraudulent 
 valuations, and hence make more difficult the work of the cus- 
 toms officers. Specific duties, on the other hand, while they 
 can be more easily administered, are open to the serious objec- 
 tion that they impose a relatively heavier burden upon less valu- 
 able goods of any class. Owing to their greater ease of collec- 
 tion, however, such specific duties now play a larger part than 
 ever before in our tariff system. 
 
 Internal Revenue Duties. Second in importance to cus- 
 toms duties are the internal revenue duties, which consist for 
 the most part of excises. Excise taxes are usually paid by stamps 
 placed upon the package of sale, although both in England and 
 the United States the tax upon the commodity is supplemented 
 by license duties upon dealers, which are also paid by stamps 
 publicly exposed by the dealer in his place of business. In 1907 
 the internal revenue duties yielded $269,666,772, more than 80 
 per cent as much as the customs receipts, of which 58 per cent 
 came from the tax on spirits, 19 per cent from the tax on tobacco, 
 22 per cent from the tax on fermented liquors, and the remainder 
 from the tax on oleomargarine, playing cards, back taxes of a 
 miscellaneous character, and penalties. 
 
 1 H. C. Adams, Science of Finance, pp. 409-410.
 
 632 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Excise taxes, like all taxes, have their grave defects, (a) Like 
 import duties, they must be levied upon articles of wide con- 
 sumption to be productive; and as they are in a large degree 
 shifted to the consumers, they frequently weigh more heavily 
 upon the poor than upon the rich, (b) This regressivity is in- 
 creased by the fact that the taxes are specific, not ad valorem, 
 so that the finer grades of domestic cigars, for instance, pay a 
 Ipwer rate of taxation than the cheaper goods, (c) In order to 
 prevent evasion of the tax, the government is compelled not only 
 to watch, but partially to direct, the process of manufacturing 
 at every step. Producers are required to give bond for the 
 faithful observance of the law, to register raw materials which 
 they buy, and to keep records of the stock on hand in accord- 
 ance with book-keeping methods prescribed for them by the 
 Internal Revenue Bureau. Such interference with private in- 
 dustry is an unfortunate but necessary part of excise taxation. 
 (d) Large systematized businesses bear such interference with 
 less effort than small concerns, and in consequence our internal 
 revenue system unquestionably exerts an influence in the direc- 
 tion of large-scale production, and possibly in the direction of 
 monopoly. The license taxes particularly, which are adjusted 
 only in the roughest way to the size of the business, unquestion- 
 ably weigh more heavily upon the small than the large dealers. 
 (c) Finally, it seems to be the almost universal opinion of com- 
 petent students that excise taxes exercise little influence upon 
 the consumption of articles whose use is believed to be deleterious. 
 An increased tax is as often followed by adulteration as by an 
 increase of the price per unit. 
 
 The advantages of the internal revenue duties, however, far 
 outweigh their defects, (a) Like the customs duties, they yield 
 an enormous revenue; but although they do fall off somewhat 
 in times of industrial depression, they are in ordinary periods 
 regular and dependable, whilst in times of war they respond 
 readily to increased rates. The increase of old duties and the 
 imposition of new duties during the Spanish War, for instance, 
 raised the receipts from $170,900,641 in 1898 to $273,437,162 in 
 1899. Many of the taxes yield a proportional increase almost as
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 633 
 
 great as the increase in the rate of the tax, a rare virtue in excise 
 taxation, as the rise of the burden usually cuts down the consump- 
 tion, (b) From the administrative standpoint they are very in- 
 expensive to collect, give rise to comparatively little fraud or 
 evasion, and the few industries which they affect have now be- 
 come so habituated to public inspection and control that the 
 latter occasion little complaint, (c) Finally, it is to be noted 
 that although excise taxes are regressive, the burden of the tax 
 is shared by producer and consumer not borne wholly by the 
 latter and the share borne by the producer varies directly with 
 the element of monopoly or differential advantage in production. 
 "Viewed as a whole, the internal revenue system is the most 
 satisfactory part of our entire financial structure, state or federal. 
 Its returns are fairly steady and reliable in times of depression. 
 Its growth is automatic. It is imposed on articles the demand 
 for which is tolerably inelastic. Its burden is not perceptibly 
 felt. It is honestly and economically collected ; and finally, it is 
 abundantly capable of yielding additional revenue, should an 
 unforeseen emergency arise." 1 
 
 Taxes on Transactions. In times of urgent need, as in the 
 War of 1812, the Civil War, and the late war with Spain, the 
 federal government has imposed taxes upon various sorts of 
 transactions. Thus, the war revenue act of 1898 imposed stamp 
 taxes on bank checks, telegrams, freight and express receipts, 
 transfers of stocks and bonds, bills of exchange, etc. In 1899, 
 the year after they were imposed, the stamp taxes yielded 
 $43,837,819. The peculiar advantage of taxes on transactions 
 is their quality of immediate productivity. As the figures just 
 quoted show, they may be made to yield largely the very yeai 
 they are imposed. Moreover, the government may make evasion 
 almost impossible by lessening the legal protection and signifi- 
 cance afforded by the documents not properly stamped. An- 
 other advantage is that they cost almost nothing to collect, as the 
 taxpayer buys the stamp himself and places it upon the docu- 
 ment. On the other hand, the general effect of such taxes is to 
 impede business ; and a check on business activity soon lessens 
 the revenue from other sources. 
 
 1 Daniels, Public Finance, p. 148.
 
 634 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 Income Taxes. What shall be done to remedy the inelasticity 
 and regressivity of federal taxation? The remedy most fre- 
 quently advocated is that of a progressive income tax. Income 
 taxes are not new in the United States. All through the colonial 
 epoch earnings or produce taxes, i.e. taxes upon special forms of 
 income, were common ; between the Revolutionary War and 
 1870, particularly after 1840, many trials of a general income 
 tax were made by the state governments; and in 1863, the federal 
 government levied a general income tax, which was retained for 
 about ten years. In 1894, the federal government again levied 
 an income tax of two per cent upon incomes in excess of $4000, 
 but the constitutionality of the act was promptly assailed, and 
 the Supreme Court, by a majority of one, and after a change in 
 the personnel of the court during the consideration of the case, 
 reversed the earlier findings and held that the income tax could 
 be levied only as a direct tax apportioned among the several 
 states in accordance with their population. An apportioned in- 
 come tax would be so obviously unjust that no one advocates its 
 adoption. But President Roosevelt has recently recommended 
 the income tax to the consideration of Congress and the American 
 people, intimating rather broadly that a reasonable and judicially 
 framed income tax might, if presented to the Supreme Court 
 again, receive a more friendly interpretation. 
 
 The income tax as employed by the state governments has 
 been a consistent and admitted failure, owing, it is stated by most 
 authorities, to the inability of assessors to tax income at source 
 and the consequent employment of self-assessment. John Smith, 
 living in Massachusetts, receives his income from a mining com- 
 pany situated in Colorado; and as the Massachusetts assessors 
 have no means of ascertaining Smith's ownership of the mining 
 stock, they are forced to depend upon his answer in declaring 
 the amount of his income. Yet it should be noted that the suc- 
 cessful German income taxes are State taxes, resting largely upon 
 declarations of the taxpayer and making comparatively little use 
 of collection at the source. The success of these taxes in Ger- 
 many is probably due to the fact that the rate is low, and the 
 people law-abiding, even in matters of taxation.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 635 
 
 A national income tax has many points of strength, (a) First 
 of all it is to be noted that in England and Italy, in which the in- 
 come tax has been given a trial, experience has justified this form 
 of taxation, according to the majority opinion of those who have 
 considered the matter. 1 (6) Moreover, it is especially noteworthy 
 that income taxation gains in economy and productiveness, and 
 wins increasing approbation as the years go by. This is in sharp 
 contrast with the experience of our states in their use of the 
 general property tax, which has grown more unjust and less 
 workable, the longer it has been tried, (c) In the third place, 
 income is as good, and perhaps better, than any other single 
 measure of ability; so that income taxation seems to be peculiarly 
 consistent with the ethical ideal that taxation should be in accord- 
 ance with ability. (</) Similarly, there is perhaps no general or 
 universal tax which, if properly enforced, would give less trouble 
 because of shifting, (e) Most important of all from the fiscal 
 standpoint is its admirable elasticity. It acts, or may be made 
 to act, as the regulator of the entire revenue system. In times of 
 prosperity, when consumption taxes are productive, a simple 
 reduction of the rate prevents the accumulation of a harmful 
 surplus. In times of stress, the revenues may be increased with 
 the minimum disturbance of industry and capital by a simple 
 increase of the rate. There can be no doubt that our federal 
 revenue system needs a direct tax of such a kind as to exercise 
 a minimum disturbing force upon industry, in order to keep a 
 wholesome balance between receipts and expenditures. 
 
 The disadvantages of a general income tax, however, are great. 
 
 (a) Its inquisitorial features are a fertile source of weakness. In 
 our opinion, people should not resent taxation simply because it 
 is inquisitorial; but if they do vigorously resent it, the fact con- 
 stitutes an element of weakness in the tax which we must take 
 into account, whether we sympathize with the feeling or not. 
 
 (b) The chief objections to the income tax, however, have to do 
 with its practicability. The federal income tax of 1894, for 
 example, contained the following provisions, each of which, the 
 
 1 In France, also, there has for some years been an active agitation for a pro- 
 gressive income tax.
 
 636 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 reader will note, raises problems that either cause injustice or 
 make room for evasion and escape, whichever way they are 
 solved. In estimating the incomes of persons, assessors were 
 directed to include: profits realized within the year from the 
 sales of real estate purchased within the two years preceding, 
 interest received or accrued upon all notes, bonds, 1 mortgages, or 
 other forms of indebtedness; the amount of all premiums on 
 bonds, notes, or coupons ; money, and the value of all personal 
 property acquired by gift or inheritance. On the other hand, 
 assessors were instructed to allow taxpayers to deduct necessary 
 expenses actually incurred in carrying on any business, occupa- 
 tion, or profession; interest due or paid out; taxes actually paid; 
 losses actually sustained from fires, storms, or shipwreck and not 
 compensated for by insurance or otherwise; and debts ascer- 
 tained to be worthless. What check had the assessor upon the 
 interest received on notes, bonds, and other forms of indebtedness? 
 How could he ascertain the profits realized upon sales of real 
 estate ? Similar openings for an indefinite amount of fraud were 
 given in the permission to deduct "necessary expenses," "interest 
 due," "losses sustained," and "debts ascertained to be worth- 
 less." On the other hand, corporations were denied the right to 
 deduct amounts carried to the account of depreciation or sinking 
 funds, and they were compelled to deduct the tax of two per cent ' 
 from all dividends which they paid to their stockholders, whether 
 their stockholders had incomes of $4000 or less. 
 
 Many of these defects are not peculiar to the tax of 1894, but 
 are inherent in the income tax principle. In estimating net in- 
 come a vast number of deductions must be made from gross in- 
 come, most of which are vague, and many of which are practically 
 indeterminate. Money rent of land, for instance, is frequently 
 less than true net income, because the property is appreciating 
 in value and because in many countries, particularly in England, 
 land ownership yields a very valuable but very intangible income 
 in the shape of increased respect from one's neighbor. Income 
 
 1 It is important to note that taxes on the interest payments upon corporate 
 bonds could not in the United States, owing to decisions of the federal court, 
 be collected at the source, or from the corporation.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 637 
 
 from mines, on the other hand, usually represents in large degree 
 a return of capital invested, since the mine is being gradually 
 exhausted ; while income from personal exertions frequently 
 represents a similar return of capital expended in costly educa- 
 tion and long apprenticeship. From the administrative stand- 
 point the income tax has almost as many weaknesses as the 
 general property tax, the number of cases in which it is easier to 
 estimate income than capital value being offset by an equal num- 
 ber of instances in which it is easier to estimate capital value than 
 income. 
 
 Progressive taxation is clearly needed somewhere in our fiscal 
 system, state or federal; and the latter system unquestionably is 
 sadly inelastic. But when all the obstacles are considered 
 court decisions, administrative weakness, the average American's 
 hostility to inquisitorial taxation, the high cost of collection, the 
 expense involved in combining progressive taxation with collec- 
 tion at the source, and the theoretical defects which the income 
 tax shares with all other general taxes it is doubtful whether 
 the income tax should be depended upon to accomplish the 
 necessary reforms. The true path of reform lies not in seeking 
 any general tax either upon property, income, or any other simple 
 basis ; it consists in combining all principles in a harmonious 
 system, using income as the basis when that is more practicable, 
 capital value as the basis when it is easier to measure wealth than 
 earnings, and resorting to consumption at perhaps a lower rate 
 when both wealth and income are particularly difficult to deter- 
 mine. 
 
 Inheritance Taxes. The recrudescence of the income tax 
 project in recent years has undoubtedly been due to a desire to 
 improve the distribution of wealth and reduce "swollen fortunes," 
 but to allow swollen fortunes to accumulate wrongly and then to 
 attempt to correct our mistake by taxing them 4 or 5 per 
 cent is to palter with justice and to play at reform. There are 
 many other remedies, more direct, more logical, more efficient. 
 Among them may properly be included the regulation and taxa- 
 tion of inheritances. 
 
 When the first edition of this work was written in 1893, inherit-
 
 638 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ance taxes were being collected in only five of the states, and so 
 strong were the objections to its wide adoption that the author 
 felt called upon to point out that unregulated collateral inherit- 
 ance was an unjustifiable survival of the clan system that was 
 being carried to ridiculous lengths at that time. Since the pub- 
 lication of the first edition, however, inheritance taxation has 
 spread rapidly, being employed in at least thirty-two states in 
 1906, and with the spread of the tax has come a most significant 
 development of progressive rating and taxation of direct as well 
 as collateral heirs. To-day one never hears of the "inherent 
 right" of decedents to control absolutely the disposition of their 
 property in perpetuity, and the right of the legislature to regulate 
 inheritance in behalf of the general social welfare is hardly dis- 
 puted. Mr. Andrew Carnegie, for instance, advocates a rate of 
 50 per cent upon the estates of millionaires. 
 
 At the present time the inheritance tax is not very productive 
 except in New York and Pennsylvania, which received in the 
 fiscal year 1905-1906, $4,713,311 and $1,507,962, respectively, 
 from this source. In all, about $10,000,000 a year is now received 
 from this source in the various states employing the tax. The 
 important fact is that the initial inertia and opposition have been 
 overcome and the ground cleared for the really efficient use of 
 this tax as a means of breaking up large fortunes and increasing 
 the revenues. The new type of the inheritance tax is well illus- 
 trated by the Wisconsin law of 1903, which applies to direct as 
 well as collateral heirs, and which graduates the rates according 
 to relationship and the amount of the individual share, and not 
 by the size of the estate. The highest rate in the Wisconsin tax 
 applying to shares in excess of $500,000 given to distant relatives 
 and strangers is 15 per cent. 
 
 Great as our progress has been in this respect, our legislation 
 still falls short of the demands of common sense. Why should 
 collateral inheritance apart from a will be allowed at all except 
 among near relatives? Why should third cousins inherit from 
 one another at all unless money is left by will ? Are third cousins 
 nearer to one than the town or city in which one has lived and 
 where one has been able to acquire a fortune? The extent to
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 639 
 
 which intestate collateral inheritance is carried is a survival of 
 the sentiment of the time when people lived in clans, and is illogi- 
 cal in our day. Right and duty should be coordinated. Ought 
 I to be compelled by law to support an uncle who is unable by 
 incapacity to earn a livelihood? Then I should inherit from 
 him; otherwise it does not seem clear that I should unless he 
 leaves me property by will. So far as practicable the circle of 
 legal duties ought, however, to be extended so as to include the 
 circle of vital relationship. The property should go to the State 
 in the absence of near relatives when no will is made. The clan 
 is dead and forgotten; ordinarily there is neither acquaintance 
 nor recognizable obligation between second cousins, not to men- 
 tion twenty-second. Inheritances thus bestowed are pure gifts, 
 wanton disturbances of existing abilities to use property. The 
 modern clan is society, and to it belong all claims to inheritance 
 falling outside the circle of vital relations. The enlightened Eng- 
 lish jurist, Jeremy Bentham, wished to restrict inheritance and 
 extend escheat, and thus abolish taxation altogether, but this is 
 going too far. 
 
 We have introduced the inheritance tax at this point between the 
 discussion of federal and state taxation because some doubt exists whether 
 it should be assigned to the federal or state governments. With two excep- 
 tions the arguments are almost all in favor of assignment to the state : (a) The 
 inheritance tax is needed to effect the separation of state and local revenues, 
 a reform earnestly advocated by most authorities. (6) Inheritance taxes 
 should not be levied by both state and federal governments, yet the latter 
 cannot prevent the state governments from making use of the tax. As it is 
 easier for one jurisdiction to refrain from introducing the tax than for many 
 jurisdictions to cease using it, the federal government should stand aside. 
 (c) Furthermore, the natural machinery of assessment the probate courts 
 can be employed by the state, but not by the federal government; and, 
 in the long run, the cost of administering the tax would probably be much 
 greater when used by the federal government. 
 
 The case for federal taxation rests upon the desirability of levying a very 
 high rate upon large inheritances, and the possibilities of unjust double 
 taxation under the state system, (a) Many persons would be disposed to 
 move away from any particular state which imposed inheritance taxes as 
 high as sound policy demands, but few would take up their residence entirely 
 outside of the United States or transfer their investments to foreign countries, 
 on this account. (6) State inheritance taxes upon personal property offer
 
 640 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 unusual temptations to double and multiple taxation. John Smith, domi- 
 ciled in Pennsylvania, dies leaving 100 shares of stock in a New Jersey 
 corporation, which shares are on deposit in a New York trust company. 
 Under these circumstances Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and New York might 
 all levy taxes upon these shares of stock. This kind of multiple taxation 
 is very much more vicious than the double taxation which would result from 
 state and federal taxation of inheritances. 
 
 The fact that the federal government cannot prohibit state inheritance 
 taxes appears to be a conclusive argument in favor of state taxation. But 
 unless the several states learn to restrain their legal powers of taxation vol- 
 untarily, and do away with multiple taxation by some species of agreement 
 concerning the equities of the situation, an intolerable condition of affairs 
 is likely to result which will add indefinite strength to the arguments in 
 favor of a federal tax. Exclusive federal taxation through a constitutional 
 amendment is unlikely, but not impossible. 
 
 STATE AND LOCAL TAXATION 
 
 General Property Tax. The key to the revenue system of our 
 state and local governments, and by far the most important tax 
 collected in the United States, is the general property tax, which 
 supplied, in 1902, 82 per cent of the tax receipts of the state and 
 local governments and 51 per cent of all taxes collected in the 
 country, national, state, and local. The most important char- 
 acteristic of this tax is suggested by the word "general," the 
 tax is levied in theory upon nearly all property, real and personal, 
 in the hands of the people. 
 
 Though the administration of the property tax differs in many 
 details among the states, it is the usual custom for assessors in 
 each community to prepare complete statements of all kinds of 
 taxable property owned by the people of the community. In 
 some states the assessors receive from all residents sworn "lists" 
 of property owned and subject to tax. By the terms of the law 
 the property is supposed to be rated at its true, full value, though 
 by the acknowledged practice of assessors and courts of review, 
 the real rates vary widely from state to state, from community 
 to community, and from individual to individual. On the basis 
 of the property valuations thus made the state and local govern- 
 ments levy direct taxes at a rate fixed from year to year according 
 to fiscal needs. The tax is then collected by local officers, and of
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 641 
 
 the whole amount the portion levied by the county and state is 
 passed on to the designated officers after each minor political 
 division has set aside its share. 
 
 As yet few economists who have written upon the subject, and 
 few state officers who have had to do with the administration of 
 the tax, have ever been able to speak of it except in terms of the 
 severest condemnation. Naturally, then, there is now a strong 
 tendency to work away from this form of taxation. Some of the 
 many serious faults which the general property tax has every- 
 where shown call for comment and explanation. 
 
 1. Unjust Apportionment. The first of the defects of the tax 
 appears in the apportionment of the state's share of the tax- 
 Each community has a narrow, selfish interest in reducing its 
 valuation that it may escape its just share of the tax. The same 
 mean struggle is especially frequent between city and country 
 districts. To correct the evil, boards of equalization are usually 
 appointed, but experience has shown that such boards usually 
 do their work in a most perfunctory way. Although earnest 
 study of assessments may and sometimes does secure a sub- 
 stantially just apportionment between county and county, this 
 equalization does not correct the glaring inequalities within 
 particular counties, and even within single assessment districts. 
 
 2. Inequality as between Realty and Personalty. In the second 
 place, the general property tax has proved grossly inequitable in 
 laying an undue proportion of its burden upon real property, 
 allowing various forms of personal property to escape with a slight 
 tax or with no tax at all. A secondary result of this inequality 
 is that the rural districts bear a disproportionate burden, since 
 the greater part of the tax-escaping personalty is owned by the 
 wealthy citizens of our cities. 
 
 3. Inequalities of City Assessments. Very similar to the 
 preceding evils is the further injustice wrought by the tax through 
 the disproportionate assessment of the pieces of real estate in 
 cities. Thus, an investigation in St. Paul, Minnesota, cover- 
 ing over twenty-five hundred pieces of property worth in the 
 aggregate more than five million dollars, showed that the average 
 ratio of assessed to true value of parcels worth less than $5000 
 
 2T
 
 642 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 was 63 per cent, while the similar ratio for parcels worth more than 
 $5000 was 56 per cent. A similar investigation made in Wis- 
 consin and covering more than 16,000 pieces of property showed 
 a glaring inequality between very small and very large properties 
 (63 per cent and 47 per cent respectively of true value), but sub- 
 stantial uniformity in the long run for properties of medium size. 
 Both investigations showed that unimproved real estate was or- 
 dinarily taxed at a very much higher ratio than improved property. 
 In many districts, also, real estate owned by non-residents is taxed 
 at a higher figure than real estate owned by residents. 
 
 4. Temptation to Dishonesty. It follows from the evils already 
 described that the general property tax leads to a shocking amount 
 of dishonesty, perjury, bribery, and other forms of corruption. 
 Indeed, as one writer has expressed it, " The general property 
 tax has gone far toward making perjury respectable and even 
 virtuous." 
 
 5. Fundamental Theoretical Defects. But the most funda- 
 mental defect of the general property tax is found in the fact that 
 it is an incongruous mixture of real and personal taxes. Real 
 estate is taxed at its situs, irrespective of ownership or the tax- 
 paying ability of the owner in a great majority of states. The 
 personal obligation of the owner to support the government under 
 which he immediately lives, is met practically everywhere by that 
 part of the tax which falls upon personal property, personal 
 property paying at the domicile of the owner. 
 
 This distinction between real and personal property is artificial, 
 inequitable, and illogically applied. Personalty, as a measure 
 of ability, ought to be accurately computed by offsetting liabilities 
 against assets, so that the taxpayer would pay only upon net 
 assets. Yet no state, with the possible exception of New Jersey, 
 grants full and complete exemption of debts; only three states 
 permit a subtraction of debts from all personalty; the rest 
 either refusing any abatement for debts whatsoever or limiting 
 the abatement to subtraction of debts from money or money 
 and credits or other restricted classes of personalty. Moreover, 
 nearly all the states manipulate their definitions of real property 
 in the most discreditable manner, causing many kinds of double
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 643 
 
 taxation. To take a single illustration: most states tax the stock 
 of foreign corporations held by resident citizens, whether the 
 corporation pays full taxes at its situs or not. Many of these 
 states tax their own or domestic corporations at full value, thus 
 indorsing the theory that a corporation should be taxed as a 
 business unit where the business is carried on. Nevertheless, 
 they attempt to tax the stock of foreign corporations when the 
 stock is the only thing they can reach. Some states, though not 
 a majority, actually tax both the shares of stock and the business 
 of domestic corporations, and then wonder that the stockholders 
 attempt to evade the inequitable obligations imposed upon them 
 by law. 
 
 Reform of the Property Tax. This brief outline of the evils 
 connected with the general property tax furnishes us with the 
 key to reform. By far the greatest reform that could possibly 
 be accomplished would result from placing the work of assess- 
 ment on a scientific basis, by appointing expert assessors under 
 civil service protection, who would give their whole time to the 
 business and hold their places during good behavior. In 1902 
 practically three fourths of the revenues collected under the 
 general property tax came from the tax on real property. Now 
 we shall undoubtedly keep the real estate tax. Nobody advocates 
 its abandonment or believes that it will be possible to get along 
 without it; and with trained assessors it would be possible to 
 make a substantially fair assessment of real property. Yet even 
 the assessment of real estate is in most places to-day wretchedly 
 unequal. We spend a great deal of time thinking out ambitious 
 fiscal reforms that will remedy the present system by revolutioniz- 
 ing it, overlooking the fact that the remedy for the deepest and 
 widest evil lies within our reach, neglected and unavailing, not 
 because we are ignorant of its potency, but because we lack the 
 will resolutely to apply it. 
 
 At the same time, no assessor, however expert and well-paid, 
 can ever be expected to assess all kinds of personal property with 
 even approximate accuracy. To persist in the attempt to assess 
 all the property of every person is simply to debase public morality 
 and convince assessors that nothing short of divine wisdom will
 
 644 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 enable them to satisfy the requirements of the law. In short, 
 the more intangible forms of personal property, if not all per- 
 sonal property, must be exempted from taxation, and the loss be 
 made up by the introduction of simpler and more workable taxes. 
 Probably the most practicable of such substitutes is the tax ad- 
 justed to the rental value of residences. Of course in individual 
 cases such a tax would violate the rules of exact justice, but with 
 suitable exemptions and proper adjustments it would be roughly 
 equitable, and it would have the striking advantages of simplicity, 
 practicability, and substantial certainty. The rental value of 
 most property can be appraised with as much accuracy as the 
 market value of real estate. Inasmuch as this tax would merely 
 replace the present property tax upon the more intangible forms 
 of personalty, it would not have to be heavy, and for this reason 
 minor cases of inequality would not be very important. 
 
 The present property tax on business and commercial concerns, 
 with its impossible requirements of stock valuations, taxation of 
 book accounts, bills receivable, and credits generally, should be 
 replaced by a business, license, or "ad valorem" tax, adjusted 
 to income in the first two cases, or to capitalized income in the 
 case of an "ad valorem" tax. The real estate and permanent 
 improvements of business concerns might be separately taxed 
 under the property tax, and a corresponding deduction made from 
 the business tax, as is common in the taxation of banks and cor- 
 porations in many states. We should then have, in place of the 
 general property tax, a real tax on accumulated or realized tangible 
 property; a personal tax on ability as measured by the rental 
 value of dwellings, and business taxes upon earnings. Although 
 the real tax would in appearance take no cognizance of mortgages 
 or debts secured by the property and no account on the surface of 
 the ability of the owner, it would not in reality wholly violate 
 the canon of taxation according to ability. The man buying land 
 on contract or subject to a mortgage, would take into account the 
 fact that he would be called upon to pay taxes upon the whole 
 value of the property, irrespective of debt or incumbrance, and 
 the price would be adjusted accordingly. Or, if he mortgaged his 
 land after he had acquired ownership, he would be indemnified
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 645 
 
 to a certain extent for paying all the taxes, by receiving a lower 
 rate of interest on his mortgage than he would be enabled to secure 
 if the creditor were liable for taxes upon that part of the property 
 covered by the mortgage. Real taxes, which take no cognizance 
 of the financial status of the owner, are not inequitable when they 
 are consistently applied and supplemented by a separate system 
 of personal taxation. 
 
 All these taxes destined to take the place of the general property 
 tax will probably, in the future, be assigned to the local govern- 
 ments. If necessary to provide enough revenue for the state, 
 however, a small state tax could equitably be levied upon real 
 estate, as the equalization of real estate assessments among the 
 larger governmental divisions, such as counties, is a comparatively 
 easy matter. Whether the state will be able to get along without 
 taxes upon real estate, depends principally upon the productivity 
 of certain corporation taxes, the proceeds of which belong logically 
 to the state as opposed to the local governments. This absorption 
 of corporation taxes by the state is already well under way in the 
 more advanced commonwealths. In 1902, for instance, New 
 York, New Jersey, and Pennsylvania, together raised $26,177,731 
 from special property and business taxes (practically corporation 
 taxes), but only $12,055,851 from the general property tax. In 
 that year Delaware made no use of the general property tax at 
 all for state purposes, Connecticut raised only $164,520 from this 
 source, and since that time New York has also abandoned general 
 property as a basis of state taxation. However, the supersession 
 of the general property tax is only true in the North Atlantic 
 states, speaking generally. In all the states and territories in 
 1902, 53 per cent of the total tax receipts came from the general 
 property tax, 34 per cent from special property and business taxes 
 principally on corporations about 1.4 per cent from poll 
 taxes, something over 6 per cent from liquor license taxes, and 
 something less than 6 per cent from other licenses and per- 
 mits. 1 
 
 Corporation Taxes. The exact way in which any corporation 
 
 1 These proportions are based upon state receipts. If local revenues were 
 included, the general property tax would appear very much more important.
 
 646 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 should be taxed depends upon a great variety of considerations, 
 which vary from place to place and from time to time. In general, 
 however, the following elements may be detected in the more 
 progressive systems of corporation taxation: I. The incorpora- 
 tion fee, to cover the clerical expenses of registering corporations 
 and the value of the privileges granted to every corporation, the 
 most important of which is that of limited liability. This charge 
 should be imposed on all joint-stock companies, should vary with 
 the amount of bonds as well as the amount of stock authorized, 
 and should be small, unless the state desires to restrict narrowly 
 the incorporation of commercial enterprises. II. The franchise 
 tax proper, to cover especially valuable privileges, such as the 
 right to use the public streets or highways, granted to most public 
 utility companies. This is essentially a contractual payment, 
 a lease or royalty rather than a tax. It should be fixed in ad- 
 vance for a definite period at as high a figure or rate as possible, 
 and when fixed, should not be tampered with by the state in 
 justice to the corporation. 1 III. The general property tax or some 
 equivalent, designed to impose upon the corporation a burden 
 equivalent to that borne by the average taxpayer of the district. 
 Inasmuch as good-will, business organization, and similar intangible 
 assets are property, property taxes imposed under this head should 
 cover not only tangible but intangible values as well, including the 
 franchise when this does not revert to the state. Corporations 
 which have received valuable franchises from the state may 
 properly be called upon to pay for the privilege (under II) as well 
 as upon the privilege (under III). 
 
 This differentiation of what may be called the bases of cor- 
 poration taxation should not be misunderstood. Many states 
 merge two or even three of these charges in a single tax, and 
 other states exempt savings banks, insurance companies, and 
 other kinds of corporations from one or all of these obligations. 
 in order to encourage thrift or foster the industry exempted. 
 
 1 However, where a long or perpetual franchise is given, provision should be 
 made for the readjustment of the rental by arbitration or in some other equitable 
 way. An illustration is found in the terms of the franchise under which the 
 Pennsylvania railroad built a tunnel under the North River and erected its mag- 
 nificent new station in New York City.
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 647 
 
 Such exemptions are often justifiable and socially helpful. But 
 unless these separate elements are kept plainly in mind, injustice 
 is almost sure to follow. To treat commercial corporations, 
 which should pay Charges I and III, on the same footing as 
 street railway or telephone companies, which should pay I, II, 
 and III, is to penalize the commercial corporation for the benefit 
 of the general public. To impose, or try to impose, Charge II 
 upon all corporations, on the theory that all of them have received 
 exceedingly valuable privileges, is to confuse general with special 
 corporation privileges, and to pave the way for " corporation- 
 baiting." Finally, although it is not necessary, we believe real 
 progress will be hastened by observing these distinctions in prac- 
 tice as well as in theoretical analysis. 
 
 The third element in corporation taxes noted above requires further dis- 
 cussion. While a distinct effort is noticeable at the present time to make 
 the tax burden upon corporations equal to that upon general property, and 
 while this represents a distinct advance inasmuch as corporations in the past 
 have escaped their due share of taxation; it is equally true that the move- 
 ment has no logical stopping place. If the general property tax is certain 
 to disappear, as most economists assert, there can be no permanency in a 
 reform designed to equate the burden of taxation upon corporations and 
 general property. 
 
 As we have seen, the general property tax will in time probably break 
 up into a tax upon real estate, a tax upon persons, and a tax upon business. 
 Corporation taxes will naturally fall in the last group. When we have 
 differentiated these taxes, however, we shall soon learn that the business tax 
 itself must be differentiated. Even at present we are forced to do this. We 
 exempt building associations from taxation, give savings banks the benefit of 
 a low rate, and impose unusually heavy taxes on saloons. This differentia- 
 tion will be extended in the future. There is as much reason to impose spe- 
 cially heavy taxes upon express and sleeping-car companies, for instance, as 
 there is to exempt churches and deal tenderly with mutual aid societies. 
 This differentiation among businesses and corporations will require in many 
 states a constitutional amendment, permitting the classification of persons 
 and property for taxation. But that is a reform which, it is hoped, will be 
 realized in the comparatively near future. 
 
 When all property is taxed where it lies, irrespective of ownership, 
 and all persons where they live, irrespective of the situs of their property, 
 then the taxation of business will stand, as it should, in a sphere of its own. 
 Within that sphere businesses that can move easily to other states will of 
 necessity be taxed lightly, as they are to-day. Businesses which derive
 
 648 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 special advantages from their environment, however, will pay a correspond 
 ingly heavy rate. Railways, to take a single illustration, will pay a higher 
 rate than some businesses, a lower rate than some others, but in any event 
 there will be no attempt to equate the tax upon railways with that upon 
 property and persons, because the railway will pay upon its property as 
 property, upon its business as business, and the owners of railway securities 
 will pay in accordance with their ability as measured by rent or some similar 
 index. 
 
 Business and License Taxes. About 12 per cent of state tax 
 receipts in 1902 came from licenses and permits, and taking the 
 state and local governments together, the revenue from this 
 source in 1902 amounted to seventy-five millions of dollars, of 
 which over fifty-five millions came from liquor li censes. The 
 high liquor license is now so common in most parts of the coun- 
 try that its social and fiscal importance needs little discussion. 
 In most Southern states, however, there is an extensive system 
 of business licenses, which supplement and partly replace the 
 general property tax. The significance and importance of the 
 business license have not hitherto been sufficiently appreciated. 
 They are levied in theory under the regulative power of the 
 government rather than the taxing power; but they have by 
 extension and multiplication become taxes for the most part, as 
 distinguished from sumptuary charges or payments for small 
 privileges. 
 
 The license system of the South is characterized by "many 
 defects. Here and there traces of class feeling are discerned, as 
 in the prohibitive licenses levied upon peddlers; and the rates 
 employed are often illogical, inconsistent, and inequitable to the 
 point of absurdity. In a few cases also, these taxes ~are high 
 enough to bar certain occupations to the man with small capital. 
 But on the whole they are among the best taxes employed by 
 American commonwealths. They are easily and cheaply col- 
 lected, very productive, cause little or no complaint, are not 
 excessive as a rule, and exercise little or no influence upon prices. 
 And in so far as they discourage the excessive multiplication of 
 small retail shops they perform the useful service of preventing 
 almost inevitable loss and bankruptcy. 
 
 The great significance of the business license is its expression
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 649 
 
 of the truth that the general property tax in its simple form is 
 unsuited to the taxation of business. Under the property tax, 
 business in general is taxed upon its tangible assets, i.e. fixed 
 plant and stock. One has only to think of the varying relation- 
 ship to taxable capacity of the plant and stock of a manufacturer, 
 a grocer, an express company, and a stock broker, to realize the 
 grave injustice of this method of taxation. In countries of con- 
 tinental Europe, as in the southern part of the United States, a 
 wide and generally satisfactory use is made of the business tax. 
 Eventually we must come to the same thing in all parts of this 
 country. But the tax should be adjusted to earnings on profits 
 in a more effective way than is now done in the South. 
 
 Poll Taxes. The poll tax is the oldest tax we have in this 
 country, and throughout the greater part of the colonial period 
 yielded more than any other source of revenue. It aroused bitter 
 opposition in many commonwealths and was prohibited by the 
 liberal constitution of Maryland at the beginning of the Revolu- 
 tionary War; but it persisted in many of the states, and still 
 remains the most important source of revenue, after the property 
 tax, in a few of the Southern states. The tax still stands on the 
 statute books of about one half of the states, and is nominally 
 employed as a highway or local tax in a still larger number of 
 commonwealths; but in many places little or no effort is made 
 to enforce it. In Wisconsin, for instance, no attempt is made to 
 collect the poll tax in more than half of the local taxing districts. 
 The poll tax is not only difficult to collect, but is regressive and, 
 when its payment is required as a prerequisite to the exercise of 
 the suffrage, results in widespread political corruption. "No 
 concealment need be made of the fact that the poll tax is used in 
 Mississippi as a means of disqualifying the negro in national 
 elections and controlling the vote in local elections." l 
 
 A BALANCED REVENUE SYSTEM 
 
 The main outlines of the distribution of taxes among the vari- 
 ous governmental units have already been suggested: to ttie 
 
 1 C. H. Brough, in Studies in Slate Taxation, Johns Hopkins University 
 Studies in Historical and Political Science, Vol. XVIII, p. 313.
 
 650 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 federal government the excise and customs duties, with taxes on 
 transactions in times of war or emergency and the taxes on inter- 
 state commerce hereafter discussed; to the state governments the 
 inheritance tax, the more important corporation taxes, and some 
 of the license taxes; to the local governments the tangible property 
 tax, the occupation tax, such of the license and business taxes as 
 are not taken by the state and federal governments, and taxes 
 or royalties on municipal franchises. Public franchises or munici- 
 pal management of public-service monopolies should be made 
 in the United States, as in Europe, to pay a considerable part 
 of the local expenses of government. 
 
 It will be observed that business and corporation taxes are to 
 be divided among the several governmental divisions. The prin- 
 ciples upon which this distribution should be made are very 
 obscure and give rise to many important problems. The first 
 and most important of these problems has to do with federal 
 control of interstate commerce. Business, like property, has a 
 natural situs for purposes of taxation, and companies engaged in 
 interstate commerce should be taxed by or under the direction 
 of the national government. 
 
 Federal Control of the Taxation of Interstate Commerce. 
 State taxation of companies engaged in interstate commerce gives 
 rise to many problems. Railways may be used as an illustra- 
 tion. The enormous difference between the value of the physical 
 property and the value of the stock and bonds or the capitalized 
 earnings of railways has called public attention to the presence 
 of vast intangible values in railway property. In order to tax 
 these values which the courts have decided to be "property" 
 the railway has to be assessed or valued as a unit an exceed- 
 ingly difficult and costly undertaking and the share of this 
 valuation belonging to the state in question has to be determined. 
 This apportionment of values to state jurisdictions is not only 
 artificial and difficult, but opens the way for much abuse. Each 
 state is tempted to adopt the method which gives it the largest 
 share of the assessed value ; and the railway has not only to adapt 
 itself to as many methods of assessment as there are states, but 
 it is not unlikely to be much overtaxed in the process, unless it
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 651 
 
 "goes into politics" with the avowed purpose of controlling 
 legislation in its own interests. 
 
 Federal control would substitute a single assessment for many 
 assessments, and one method of apportionment for the great 
 variety of conflicting methods now in use. These essential re- 
 forms having been determined upon, the other problems of fed- 
 eral control * may be settled in a variety of ways, (a) The federal 
 government might confine its work to valuation and apportion- 
 ment, certifying to each state the valuation of the property as- 
 signed to it, to be taxed there at the same rate as other similar 
 property. This plan, however, assumes that railways will con- 
 tinue to be taxed in accordance with the underlying principles 
 of the general property tax. (b) Or the federal government 
 might permit the physical property of railways to be taxed by 
 the states in which it is situated and confine itself to taxes on the 
 business as such, a method in harmony with the general plan 
 of business taxation suggested above, (c) Or it might wholly 
 prohibit state taxation of either the property or business of inter- 
 state companies, although the constitutionality of such prohibi- 
 tion is particularly doubtful. 
 
 Assuming that one of the last two plans will be adopted, the 
 federal government could (a) either refund the proceeds of the 
 tax upon interstate business to the various states, in proportion 
 to the amount of business done in each state or some other equi- 
 table method of apportionment; or (b) retain the revenue itself 
 to be used in meeting emergency needs or in reducing the con- 
 sumption taxes which now weigh so heavily upon the poor. 
 
 The constitutionality of the whole project of federal control 
 is in grave doubt, although this aspect of the subject cannot be 
 discussed here. But that Congress will eventually be forced to 
 use all the power that it possesses to bring order out of the exist- 
 ing chaos seems as inevitable as it is desirable. 
 
 Separation of the Sources of State and Local Revenues. Just 
 as Congress should assume control, if possible, of the taxation of 
 interstate railways, express, telegraph, sleeping car and steam- 
 
 1 The desideratum is federal control of the taxation of interstate corporations, 
 not necessarily federal taxation.
 
 652 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ship companies, so the state government should assume control 
 of the taxation of inter-urban railways, telephone companies, and 
 other concerns whose business is "state-wide" in scope. In 
 recent years economists have urged the state to set aside enough 
 such taxes for its own exclusive use, until with such revenues 
 as the state derived from inheritance, poll, and license taxes it 
 would be able to meet expenses without resorting to general levies 
 upon property. 
 
 This programme is in the main admirable, and would bring to 
 an end all those evils arising out of the efforts of local districts 
 to escape state taxation by underassessment of property. But 
 the project has dangers and defects of its own. In the first place 
 it does not provide for the abolition of the general or personal 
 property tax within the local districts, but permits the latter to 
 persist in the attempt to tax stocks and bonds, money and credits, 
 manufacturing plant and merchants' stocks. In our opinion the 
 attempt to tax all kinds of property should be abolished by the 
 state legislatures, without waiting for the agreement of the local 
 governments. 
 
 In the second place, it would be unwise for the state govern- 
 ment to monopolize corporation, inheritance, and license taxes 
 merely to get upon an independent footing, and then leave the 
 local governments to shift for themselves. Compared with local 
 taxation, state taxation is really a matter of small importance, 
 and the great problem of commonwealth finance is how the large 
 cities, in particular, are to meet the enormous expenditures thrust 
 upon them by the mere growth and congestion of population. 
 Take the liquor license, for example. The saloon contributes 
 very materially to the expenses of the city government. If the 
 state were to take over the liquor license for its own use, it would 
 deprive the city of one of its most logical and necessary sources 
 of revenue. For similar reasons the state should be exceedingly 
 careful in selecting the corporations upon which local taxes are 
 not to be levied. To prohibit the taxation of railways by the 
 local governments is wise, but to deprive them of the power to 
 tax light, heat, and power companies, as was recommended by 
 the California Commission on Revenue and Taxation, would be
 
 PUBLIC REVENUES 653 
 
 going too far in the average state. 1 In short, there is a logical 
 and important connection between business or property and 
 particular divisions of government. The true method is to ascer- 
 tain the character of this relationship and assign the business or 
 property, for purposes of taxation, to the proper governmental 
 division. Then if the state has too much revenue, it may be 
 apportioned to the local districts. If it has too little, the re- 
 mainder may be raised by taxes upon the equalized value of real 
 estate. Experience has shown that it is a comparatively easy 
 matter to equalize real estate values among counties or similar 
 divisions, with all the accuracy necessary for the equitable distri- 
 bution of a light tax. 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 1. Why are the terms "direct " and "indirect" taxes particularly vague 
 and equivocal ? 
 
 2. Explain why no protection is given the home producer when the 
 import duty is shifted upon the foreigner. 
 
 3. What is the greatest fiscal defect of American customs taxation? Can 
 this defect be remedied ? 
 
 4. Are excise taxes ethically justifiable ? Do they materially check con- 
 sumption when imposed upon alcoholic beverages and tobacco? 
 
 5. Do you know of any state which levies an income tax at the present 
 time ? Is the tax successful ? 
 
 6. What arguments in favor of introducing a federal income tax can 
 fairly be derived from European experience? 
 
 7. Should income representing not earnings but simple return of capital 
 be taxed? Should income which is saved and immediately reinvested be 
 taxed ? Is it not double taxation to tax savings and the earnings from such 
 savings as well ? 
 
 8. The inheritance tax has been justified as a compulsory payment 
 according to accidental or suddenly enhanced ability. Is this explanation 
 logical ? 
 
 9. Should corporations be taxed at the same rate as unincorporated 
 business concerns? Should any definite relation between the two kinds of 
 taxes be maintained? 
 
 10. Contrast the taxation of national banks in your own state with the 
 taxation of trust companies, ordinary commercial or manufacturing corpora- 
 tions, and unincorporated business concerns. 
 
 1 Although the recommendation of the California Commission is doubtless 
 justified for California by peculiar local conditions.
 
 654 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 11. What difference is there between real and personal taxes ? Are real 
 taxes inequitable ? 
 
 12. Are assessors elected or appointed in your own state? Do they re- 
 quire taxpayers to declare their personal property in great detail ? Do the 
 local assessment rolls contain separate figures for real estate and improve- 
 ments? Is the property of non-residents specially designated? 
 
 13. Why is the general property tax particularly unsuited to the taxation 
 of business and professional men ? 
 
 14. Should the federal government, if it possesses the power, make the 
 taxation of interstate commerce corporations uniform throughout the United 
 States ? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Selected Readings in Public Finance, Chaps VII-XIX; 
 and " The Taxation of Corporations in Massachusetts," Quarterly 
 Journal of Economics, Vol. XXI, pp. 181-246. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Evolution of Industrial Society, Chap. VII, "The Inheritance 
 of Property," pp. 271-314. 
 
 HOLLANDER, J. H., Ed. Studies in Stats Taxation, Johns Hopkins 
 University Studies in Historical and Political Science, Series XVIII, 
 passim. 
 
 McCREA, R. C. "The Taxation of Personal Property in Pennsylvania," 
 Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XXI, pp. 52-95. 
 
 Report of the Industrial Commission. "Taxation," Vol. XIX, pp. 1031- 
 1069; "Taxation in Various States and in Canada with Special 
 Reference to the Taxation of Corporations," Vol. XI, Part VII ; 
 "Taxation of Transportation Companies," Vol. IX, pp. 1006-1091. 
 
 Reports of State Tax Commissions. Upon the topics indicated see " The 
 Massachusetts Tax System and its Workings," Massachusetts Com- 
 mission of 1897, pp. 1-73; " Public Service Corporations," Wisconsin 
 Commission, 1901, pp. 72-121; "Taxation of Credits," ibid. 1903, 
 pp. 88-144 ! " Mortgage Taxation," ibid., 1907, pp. 303 et seq. ; " Railway 
 Taxation," Ontario Commission, 1905. 
 
 WEST, MAX. The Inheritance Tax, Chap. VII, " Inheritance Taxes in the 
 United States," and Chap. IX, "Economic Theory of the Inheritance 
 Tax."
 
 BOOK IV 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT
 
 CHAPTER XXXVI 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 
 
 The Development of Economic Thought. If society were not 
 progressive, history would be of comparatively little value. The 
 study of the present would give us all the essential facts needed to 
 understand society, and, problems once settled or institutions once 
 explained, the work would not have to be done over again. All 
 this, however, is the very contrary of the truth, so contrary, indeed, 
 that one of the most difficult things that either the scientist or the 
 statesman and reformer has to do is to overcome this idea that 
 institutions are fixed. Society moves but slowly, to be sure, and 
 its development is so much slower than that of the individual that 
 he easily overlooks its changes altogether. 
 
 The relation is much like that of a tourist to a glacier. He 
 climbs nimbly over its rigid mass with as little sense of under- 
 lying movement as when he climbs the mountain itself. He maps 
 out its confines and its jutting peaks with as much accuracy as the 
 rest of the landscape. He returns to-morrow and next year and 
 sees no important changes, and so thinks his investigation is com- 
 plete. But let a century elapse, and his map is wholly wrong. 
 Another observer stumbling upon it wonders that a man could 
 have made such blunders, and makes his map with painstaking 
 exactness. But he may be as wrong as the first; indeed, he is as 
 wrong unless he has discovered the cause of the discrepancy. The 
 glacier moves. This slow but constant and resistless motion is 
 the cause of every seam and crevasse, of the huge piles of bowlders 
 at the sides and base, in short, of the great landmarks upon the 
 map. The tourist may disregard it, but not the engineer who 
 shapes the interests of a remote posterity. 
 
 The social sciences have a similar experience. Map succeeds 
 map, each claiming that former maps are false, and assuming that 
 2u 657
 
 658 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 conditions are fixed and that present and local explanations apply 
 to all times and places, until finally the discrepancy is explained 
 by the great law of social movement, which in turn becomes the 
 object of investigation. When this movement is discovered, a new 
 importance attaches to past explanations. While they may have 
 made the mistake of supposing that their conclusions were of per- 
 manent and universal application, they contain much valuable 
 observation, from which we may discover the laws of progress. 
 Of course these maps of society have been imperfect much 
 more so than maps of glaciers. The facts are so complex, and 
 men are so influenced by their particular environment, that no one 
 man ever sees all the facts or arranges them in their true relations. 
 Nevertheless, these observations have great value to us, and their 
 onesidedness is usually apparent. Moreover, it is the very dis- 
 covery of these limitations which makes our own thought broader 
 and more comprehensive. 
 
 Our study of history thus has two phases, never separable in 
 practice, though distinct in character, the history of economic 
 life and the history of economic thought. With the former our 
 study began, and its importance has been easily felt. The latter 
 was reserved until the close. No sound system of economic 
 thought can be built up without taking account of past systems. 
 The thought of the present must master the thought of the past if 
 it would be better than the thought of the past. 
 
 Economic Ideas in the Ancient World. The assertion is some- 
 times made, or at least the impression is frequently given, that no 
 economic thought existed until Adam Smith. This impression is 
 erroneous, and derives its plausibility from the fact that before 
 Adam Smith economic subjects were treated either disjointedly 
 and in a monographic way, or else in connection with ethics and 
 political philosophy. But in treating economics in connection 
 with ethics and politics, the older writers were merely following an 
 instinctive method of dealing with economic truths, to which in a 
 certain degree later writers are returning. Indeed, if we are to 
 derive the most possible benefit from this brief survey of the devel- 
 opment of economic thought, it is necessary to begin many cen- 
 turies before Adam Smith, with the Greeks.
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 659 
 
 The Greeks. The three writers among the Greeks most inter- 
 esting to the economist are Plato, Aristotle, and Xenophon. Both 
 Xenophon and Aristotle (or, more probably, some unknown dis- 
 ciple of Aristotle) have treatises upon the specific subject of (Eco- 
 nomics, but these are devoted principally to domestic economy, or 
 the management of the household; and the more important eco- 
 nomic ideas of the Greek writers are derived from their works 
 which deal primarily with political and ethical subjects. 
 
 Plato describes a Utopia in his Republic. His aim was to picture 
 an ideal society in which the ills of society were to be corrected by 
 a communistic State, and he included a communism even of wives 
 and children, going farther than modern communists. The com- 
 munism of Plato admitted, strange as it may seem, slavery, on 
 which his social superstructure indeed rested as a base. The Laws 
 of Plato is a more practical work. It aims to present not the best 
 possible state, but only the second best, and deals to a greater 
 extent with existing institutions. 
 
 Aristotle's principal work for us is the Politics, and it is indeed 
 one of the most remarkable books in the world's history. Its in- 
 fluence is strongly felt to-day, for it was carefully studied by theo- 
 logians of the middle ages, and through them entered into the 
 thought and life of their time; and the thought and life of their 
 time can be seen by the careful student to have entered in a thou- 
 sand ways into the institutions of the twentieth century. Glad- 
 stone said the Politics of Aristotle was one of the three books from 
 which he had learned most. 
 
 While Plato tacitly accepted slavery, Aristotle actively defended 
 the institution of slavery, describing the slave as an "animated 
 tool," and insisting that slave labor was necessary in order that the 
 ruling classes might have the leisure for statecraft, art, and litera- 
 ture. Both Plato and Aristotle, also, fully appreciated the advan- 
 tages of the division of labor, and understood, in consequence, 
 that a certain amount of traffic and exchange are necessary. But 
 both writers shared the common prejudice against trade and com- 
 merce; what one man gained in exchange, they thought, some 
 other man lost; and to live by trade was in their eyes despicable. 
 Aristotle, moreover, defended the institution of private property,
 
 660 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 and formulated surprisingly accurate ideas about money and its 
 functions; but he condemned interest taking because, as he ex- 
 pressed it, money is barren. 
 
 Perhaps the most characteristic quality of Greek economic 
 thought, speaking generally, is the thorough subordination of eco- 
 nomic to ethical and political considerations. The object of life, 
 in their view, was self-knowledge or self-realization, not the acqui- 
 sition of riches, and they refused to regard wealth as an object of 
 fundamental importance to either the individual or the State. 
 Plato, indeed, in certain parts of his writings, defends the ascetic 
 idea that human wants are to be satisfied, not by the improvement 
 of productive processes, but by the repression of those wants them- 
 selves. 
 
 The Romans. While the economic institutions of the Romans 
 and the manifestations of their character in their economic life 
 will repay investigation, they were not remarkable for independent 
 thought. Their economic ideas, like their philosophical doctrines, 
 were borrowed from the Greeks, and show the same general char- 
 acteristics which the ideas of Plato and Aristotle do. Commerce 
 and trade were held in contempt, particularly when carried on in a 
 small way. Interest taking was by some thought to be "as bad 
 as murder." Agriculture, on the other hand, was esteemed to be 
 worthy of the noblest citizens, and a "return to the soil" in later 
 Roman times was frequently recommended as a cure for the pre- 
 vailing degeneracy. Pliny said the great estates, the latif undid, 
 together with slave labor and the destruction of the small inde- 
 pendent farmer, caused the downfall of Rome. Among other agri- 
 cultural problems discussed by the Romans were those of intensive 
 versus extensive culture, and slave versus free labor. 
 
 The jurists are, however, the most important of all. Whatever 
 may be its imperfections, the Roman law, the corpus juris civilis, 
 is the most remarkable legal system the world has ever seen and 
 for training in careful and accurate statement is unsurpassed. 
 Probably, as a training for economic studies, Roman law is among 
 the most valuable branches of learning. It gives us also invaluable 
 information about the economic institutions and measures of Rome. 
 
 Christianity. To the economic thought of the time Chris-
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 661 
 
 tianity brought the revolutionary ideas of the honorableness of 
 toil and the equality of men before God. The philosophy of the 
 Stoics had brought analogous ideas to the attention of the re- 
 stricted intellectual world of the day, but Christianity popularized 
 these ideas. The clergy were encouraged to earn their livelihood 
 by manual labor, and laymen were exhorted to free their slaves as 
 soon as they had become Christians. With respect to money and 
 trade, however, the effect of Christianity was to strengthen and im- 
 press the teachings of Aristotle. 
 
 The Middle Ages. As the power of the Church increased, its 
 economic ideas found more formal expression in the treatises of 
 the schoolmen and mediaeval theologians who expounded the 
 church or canon law. Indeed, in the corpus juris canonici we 
 have a definite system of economic thought which, while it was 
 largely theoretical and intended originally for the ecclesiastical 
 courts, came in time to be widely applied in secular affairs through 
 the power of the confessional, the pulpit, and the wide jurisdiction 
 of the ecclesiastical courts. 
 
 The doctrines of the canonists were derived, in part, from bib- 
 lical injunctions against usury and the pursuit of wealth. The 
 early Christian fathers frequently went so far as to condemn private 
 property and set up the ideal of communism among the faithful. 
 But this was only an ideal, and private property was early recog- 
 nized as a necessary evil resulting from the fall of man. This 
 ideal, however, was powerful enough to keep alive the doctrine 
 that the maintenance of the poor was not a matter of philanthropy, 
 but a binding obligation, in the words of Thomas Aquinas, the 
 most distinguished canonist, a debitum legate. 
 
 Following the philosophers of Greece and Rome, and in sym- 
 pathy with the scriptural attitude toward wealth, trade and com- 
 merce were regarded as greatly inferior to agriculture and handi- 
 work as a source of livelihood. It was still believed that what the 
 seller made by trade the buyer necessarily lost. As commerce 
 developed, however, trade had to be recognized by the Church. 
 In doing so, the canon writers formulated the doctrine of justum 
 pretium, that every commodity has a just price, or value, which it 
 is sinful for the seller to exceed. The modern trades-union doc- 

 
 662 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 trine of a fair wage, and the decisions of our courts concerning rea- 
 sonable charges for gas, railway services, etc., illustrate the hold 
 which ethical ideas of this sort have even at the present time. 
 According to a very general idea, the just price of an article is 
 the amount required to enable its producer to live in accordance 
 with the accepted standard of living of his class. 
 
 The next most important economic doctrine of the canonists 
 was the prohibition of usury, which originally signified any inter- 
 est, not necessarily excessive interest, on a loan. The argument 
 against interest was based upon scriptural strictures against usury, 
 and upon Aristotle's argument that money is barren. Interest 
 taking by the clergy had been prohibited as early as the fourth 
 century; but in 1311, at the Council of Vienna, interest was pro- 
 hibited " absolutely and universally," regardless of the civil law; 
 and by the middle of the fourteenth century, the prohibition of 
 interest had, in many places, been incorporated into the civil law. 
 Little by little, however, the Church was forced to change its atti- 
 tude, and in the middle of the sixteenth century (1545) a statute 
 was passed in England legalizing an annual interest rate not in 
 excess of 10 per cent. By this time the teachings of the canonists 
 were fast giving way to the doctrines of mercantilism. 
 
 Economic Ideas in Modern Times. Before the close of the 
 sixteenth century, the temporal power of the Church had been 
 undermined by the development of the great modern monarchies, 
 and in economic thought religious considerations were replaced by 
 political necessities. The problem of the Church the universal 
 establishment of the Kingdom of God upon earth gave way to a 
 newer problem the maintenance and aggrandizement of rival 
 states. The latter were in pressing need of ready money with 
 which to build navies and support armies. How to increase public 
 revenue and national wealth became the absorbing questions of 
 the time. 
 
 Mercantilism. The mercantile system, also called Colbert- 
 ism, restrictive system, and commercial system, obtained from 
 the early part of the sixteenth century until late in the eighteenth 
 century, and its influence is still felt. Mercantilism is not, strictly 
 speaking, the product of a school of political economists, but
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 663 
 
 rather the name given to that economic policy of statesmen and to 
 those detached economic views of writers which prevailed during 
 this period. Most prominent among the statesmen who were 
 mercantilists may be named Colbert, of France, Frederick the 
 Great, of Prussia, and Cromwell, of England. Serra, an Italian, 
 early in the seventeenth century, presented a moderate and sys- 
 tematic statement of their views in a work entitled A Brief Treatise 
 on Causes which make Gold and Silver abound where there are 
 no Mines. Thomas Mun, in England, a generation later, wrote 
 a valuable treatise from the standpoint of the mercantilists, called 
 England's Treasure by Foreign Trade: or the Balance of our Trade 
 the Rule of our Treasure, while Sir James Steuart's Inquiries into 
 the Principles of Political Economy, published in 1767, may be 
 regarded as closing the development of the theory of mercantilism. 
 
 The principal characteristics of mercantilism the efforts to 
 increase the stock of precious metals within the country, to main- 
 tain a favorable balance of trade, to increase the population and 
 foster manufactures, if necessary at the expense of agriculture 
 have been described elsewhere, and need not be repeated at this 
 point. In attempting to apply these theories, however, the states- 
 men of this epoch instinctively turned to that instrument the 
 law with whose use they were most familiar, and statutory 
 restrictions were multiplied until mercantilism in one sense be- 
 came practically synonymous with governmental interference. 
 Toward the end of the eighteenth century, however, the commer- 
 cial position of England, for example, became so strong that many 
 of her industries found themselves crippled and confined by the 
 very laws which had protected their infancy, and a reaction 
 against mercantilism set in. The reaction, naturally, took the 
 form of a movement in favor of agriculture and against govern- 
 mental interference in economic and industrial affairs. In obedi- 
 ence to the needs of a new epoch, political economy lent itself to a 
 propaganda in support of the doctrine of industrial liberty. 
 
 The Physiocrats. The reaction against mercantilism found 
 its first thorough and scientific expression at the hands of the 
 French Physiocrats. Quesnay, a physician, Gournay, a merchant, 
 and Turgot, the statesman, are their three principal authors. Po-
 
 664 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 litically, the physiocrats taught the doctrine of natural laws and 
 rights, and as a consequence loudly proclaimed the maxim of 
 laissez-faire, that is, that the government should not interfere with 
 private enterprise. Economically, they exalted the importance 
 of agriculture, and maintained that manufactures and commerce, 
 which merely change the form or position of raw materials, are 
 barren and unproductive (though useful when subordinated to 
 agriculture) ; but that agriculture yields a net surplus produit 
 net over and above the expenses of production. The physio- 
 crats must thus be credited with originating the fertile economic 
 doctrine of surplus value a reward or premium appearing in 
 production for which nature rather than man is responsible, and 
 which is not required to induce men to put forth the effort neces- 
 sary to produce wealth. 
 
 Many of the other doctrines of the physiocrats follow logically 
 from the primacy which they accorded to agriculture. Since agri- 
 culture is the sole ultimate source of wealth, they maintained that 
 the revenue of the State should be raised by a single direct tax 
 the impdt unique levied upon land. All taxes must, they 
 thought, in the end come out of rent anyway; and it was better 
 that the landlord should pay them at once instead of waiting until 
 they had passed through five or six hands and various profits had 
 added to their amount. Naturally the physiocrats were ardent 
 champions of free trade. They encouraged also the consumption 
 of agricultural products, "in order that the produit net might be 
 increased," and were generous champions of the importance and 
 rights of the downtrodden peasantry. " Pauvres paysans, pauvre 
 royaume; pauvre royaume, pauvre roi," was the motto of Ques- 
 nay's Tableau Economique, the most important treatise of the 
 physiocratic school. 
 
 Adam Smith. In 1776 Adam Smith published his Inquiry 
 into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, the most influ- 
 ential economic treatise ever written. " The life of almost every- 
 one in England, perhaps of everyone," said Bagehot, "is different 
 and better in consequence of it." His writings are found to be 
 very similar to those of the physiocrats, but further developed and 
 modified by his Scotch training and habit of mind. We find in
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 665 
 
 Adam Smith the doctrines of free trade, non-interference, and 
 natural laws, yet all stated more guardedly. Although he does 
 not regard agriculture as exclusively productive, he does show a 
 partiality for agriculture, for in this branch of production, he says, 
 nature labors along with man. He emphasized the importance of 
 permitting each individual to follow his own self-interest as a 
 means of promoting national prosperity, but he was not unmindful 
 of the existence of altruistic motives in mankind. He accords full 
 recognition to the motives of sympathy and kindness in his Theory 
 of Moral Sentiments. But the net result of Smith's teaching was 
 to strengthen and emphasize the laissez-faire trend of economic 
 thought in his time. " Two conceptions," said Arnold Toynbee, 
 "are woven into every argument of the Wealth of Nations, the 
 belief in the supreme value of individual liberty, and a conviction 
 that man's self-love is God's providence, that the individual in 
 pursuing his own interest is promoting the welfare of all." 
 
 Economic Thought in the Nineteenth Century. The Classical 
 School. The economic philosophy which prevailed during the 
 first half of the nineteenth century is variously designated as the 
 classical, Ricardian, English, or orthodox school. The earlier 
 authors of this period were Jeremy Bentham (1738-1 842), Thomas 
 Robert Malthus (1766-1834), David Ricardo (1772-1823), James 
 Mill (1773-1836), and John Ramsay McCulloch (1770-1864). 
 In all of these writers we find the utilitarian philosophy, a deduct- 
 ive method, and the feeling that the outlook for the mass of the 
 laborers was not a hopeful one. They elaborated economic prin- 
 ciples, supposed to be good for all times and places, with the posi- 
 tiveness that one expects to find only in the mathematical or 
 physical sciences. 
 
 Bentham's great work was the formulation and propaganda of 
 the utilitarian philosophy, with its famous first principle or goal 
 of social action the greatest happiness of the greatest number. 
 
 Malthus' s principal contribution, contained in his celebrated 
 work, The Theory of Population, has already been discussed. 
 While Malthus was himself a particularly charitable and benevo- 
 lent friend of the working classes, his doctrine of population con- 
 tributed more than any other single thing to make the political
 
 666 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 economy of the Classical School harsh and gloomy. It seemed 
 to say that although wages were low they could be no higher, 
 because if by some fortunate chance wages increased, population 
 was sure to multiply until the wage was forced back to the old 
 level. Poor relief and trades-union activities were both useless. 
 The woe of the poor was due to their own lack of foresight, and 
 could be removed by the poor alone. It was taught "that he who 
 brought children into the world without adequate provision for 
 them should be left to the punishment of nature." The responsi- 
 bility of poverty was thus thrust upon the poor themselves; the 
 rich were soothed with the assurance that they were not primarily 
 responsible for the condition of affairs; and political economy 
 was diverted from the consideration of its truest problem the 
 amelioration of poverty to a discussion of the problems con- 
 nected with capital and trade. The importance of the Malthusian 
 proposition in economic philosophy in the first half of the nine- 
 teenth century can scarcely be exaggerated. 
 
 Ricardo was perhaps the first economist who adequately realized 
 the importance of the problem of the distribution of wealth. The 
 backbone of his distributive system was the Malthusian propo- 
 sition. Ricardo believed that as population increased, society 
 would be forced to resort to poorer and poorer soils in order to 
 obtain food; and as this took place an increasing share of the 
 product of industry would go to the landlord in the shape of eco- 
 nomic rent. The division of the remaining product between labor 
 and capital, in Ricardo's view, was determined largely by the "iron 
 law of wages"; that is to say, the laborer would receive enough to 
 purchase the necessaries and conveniences required to support 
 him and his family in their customary style of living, while the 
 residue would go to capital in the form of interest and profits. 
 Profits were thus the "leavings of wages." With the passage of 
 time and the settlement of a country, then, Ricardo's theory of 
 distribution taught that rent would absorb a larger and a larger 
 share of the product, wages about the same amount, while profits 
 would dwindle both absolutely and relatively. 
 
 Ricardo's principal work is called Principles of Political 
 Economy and Taxation. It was published in 1817, and in it
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 667 
 
 Ricardo elaborates, although he did not originate, the usually re- 
 ceived doctrine of rent, which, modified and developed, is the one 
 presented in this book. His ideas in general have a markedly 
 pessimistic tinge. Rent, he said, is due to the niggardliness, not 
 to the bounty, of nature; and his theory of distribution emphasized 
 the natural diversity of interest between wage receivers and profit 
 makers, and the antagonism between the interests of landowners 
 and all other classes of society. Personally he was a kind man, 
 and sincerely devoted to the advancement of humanity. Ricardo 
 is remarkable for his extreme development of the abstract deduct- 
 ive method, and it is noteworthy that this development is not in 
 the writings of a professional scholar, but in the work of one of 
 the most successful bankers and brokers of his day. Socialists 
 claim that developing still farther, or to their logical outcome, the 
 teachings of Ricardo, they arrive at socialism. 
 
 John Stuart Mill, who lived from 1806-1873, closed one period 
 in the development of economic science and began another in Eng- 
 land. He started as a thoroughgoing follower of Ricardo, pre- 
 served the old doctrines of value, rent, and profits, and advocated 
 laissez-faire as a general principle of political expediency. But 
 in his later years Mill advocated the diffusion of property through 
 the regulation and taxation of inheritances, indorsed the appro- 
 priation by the State of the future unearned increment of land, and 
 emphasized an important distinction between the production and 
 distribution of wealth. " The laws and conditions of the produc- 
 tion of wealth," he said, "partake of the nature of physical truths. 
 There is nothing optional or arbitrary in them. ... It is not so 
 with the distribution of wealth. That is a matter of human insti- 
 tutions solely. The things once there, mankind, individually or 
 collectively, can do with them as they like. . . . The distribution 
 of wealth, therefore, depends upon the laws and customs of society. 
 The rules by which it is determined are what the opinions and 
 feelings of the community make them, and are very different in 
 different ages and countries; and might be still more different, if 
 mankind so chose." 
 
 The old and the new doctrines found in Mill's Principles of 
 Political Economy do not harmonize, however, and the result is a
 
 668 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 work one of the most valuable of modern times, yet full of incon- 
 sistencies. Nevertheless, Mill will always be regarded as the 
 culmination of the school usually known as the English deduct- 
 ive or classical school. Most of the work of the school was deduct- 
 ive; that is, they reasoned by singling out a few main facts of the 
 external physical world and human nature familiar to all, and 
 showing how men must act under the guidance of these laws. 
 None of these economists pretended that the few laws which they 
 considered were the whole of human nature, though they have 
 sometimes been interpreted as if they did so; but they thought that 
 the great multitude of motives which influenced men were too 
 complex to be analyzed, and only one or two (chiefly self-interest) 
 could "be reduced to any assignable law." It is plain that such a 
 system of economics was highly ideal and never realized in actual 
 life. The exceptions to its rules seemed more numerous than the 
 cases to which the rules applied. Men could not long be content 
 with an economics which told them one thing, while life constantly 
 told them something different, and often very different. The result 
 was a reaction toward a fuller recognition of the real facts of life. 
 Socialism. Mill's change of heart resulted partly from his 
 study of the socialist writers, who voiced the earliest and most 
 thoroughgoing protest against the views of the classical economists. 
 Modern socialistic doctrine may conveniently be dated from 
 William Godwin's Inquiry concerning Political Justice, the first 
 edition of which appeared in 1793. Godwin and the early French 
 idealists and communists Cabet, Saint-Simon, Fourier, etc., 
 began the attack on the ethical and political views of the orthodox 
 political economy. Later the attack was continued in a some- 
 what more practical and realistic way by writers such as Wil- 
 liam Thompson and Robert Owen in England, Bazard and Louis 
 Blanc in France, Rodbertus, Lasalle, and Marx in Germany. The 
 foundation of classical political economy was laissez-faire, and its 
 doctrinal structure was built around the system of private capi- 
 talistic enterprise. Socialism in essence was a thorough protest 
 against laissez-faire and the private ownership of property. 
 Pierre LeRoux used the word "socialism" in 1838* with the 
 very purpose of expressing the antithesis of individualism. 
 
 1 It was used before this in England by the followers of Robert Owen.
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 669 
 
 In recent times, largely under the influence of Karl Marx, 
 socialism has acquired a distinctive economic theory of its own. 
 Marx, in his work on Capital, is apparently as abstract, deductive, 
 and pessimistic as any of the classical school, but at bottom his 
 whole theory was directed against those fundamental institutions 
 of our social order which the classical economists took for granted. 
 Marx has been credited by some as the discoverer of the material- 
 istic or economic interpretation of history, and the whole tendency 
 of the modern scientific socialists has been to emphasize the evo- 
 lutionary standpoint. 
 
 The Sociologists. Among other influences which broadened 
 Mill's conception of economic science, and induced him to temper 
 the rigor of his early teachings, were the works of Auguste Comte 
 (1798-1857), the founder of modern sociology. Comte was espe- 
 cially severe in his criticism of the methods of the classical econo- 
 mists. He denied, in particular, that it is possible to develop a 
 helpful science of economics distinct from history, ethics, and 
 politics. Not only must these fields, he maintained, be cultivated 
 in common, but the work must be done by inductive, as distinct 
 from deductive, methods. To the classical assumption that a uni- 
 versal science of economics could be formulated, true for all 
 times and places, he opposed the theory that there is in society an 
 ordered change or evolution, and that the capitalistic stage, to 
 which the classical economics conformed, must be studied in con- 
 nection with the past and the future. Economics, he particularly 
 insisted, cannot be divorced from history. 
 
 The Historical School. This particular line of thought was 
 taken up in Germany about 1850 by three young Germans, 
 Roscher, Knies, and Hildebrand, who vigorously assailed the doc- 
 trines of the classical school. They went back to the old premises 
 self-interest, private property, demand, and supply and 
 traced out the historical development of economic life, coming to 
 the conclusion that economic policies were not absolutely, but only 
 relatively, true. They denied that economic science can discover 
 laws which hold true for all times and all places. They empha- 
 sized the importance of the inductive method, of minute investiga- 
 tions into facts, and the study of legal institutions, custom, and
 
 670 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 ethics in their relation to economic life, while most members of the 
 school entertained a strong sympathy for state policies of reform. 
 Among the later writers of this group we may mention especially 
 Gustav Schmoller. 
 
 Owing to the political ferment in Germany during the infancy 
 of the historical school and the formation of the German Empire 
 when this reaction against the classical economists was at its height, 
 German political economy of the last half of the nineteenth century 
 was impregnated with a striking nationalistic spirit which sepa- 
 rated it even further from the cosmopolitanism of the English 
 writers. The creation of a new state is almost invariably attended 
 by the enactment of restrictive legislation, looking to the amalga- 
 mation of the diverse elements incorporated into the new state 
 and the protection of its industries from foreign competition. 
 Laissez-faire, under these conditions, is particularly difficult 
 to maintain. The *new national economy of Germany seemed to 
 voice these political necessities. Like the classical economy of Eng- 
 land, it was a creature of its own time and its own environment. 
 
 The Economic Optimists. The classical English economists 
 have often been called pessimists. This is too strong a term, in- 
 asmuch as they all saw hope for improvement. What can be said 
 is that they developed pessimistic tendencies. Take it as we will, 
 the Malthusian doctrine of population is tinged with pessimism, 
 and so also are the Ricardian ideas of the action of nature as seen 
 in the rent of land and in his scheme of distribution. In oppo- 
 sition to English economists, there was developed elsewhere, about 
 the middle of the nineteenth century, a scheme of thoroughgoing 
 economic optimism, and this was presented in a more unqualified 
 way by Frederic Bastiat (1801-1850), than by any one else; so 
 much so that economic optimism at once brings to the mind of any 
 economist familiar with the history of economic thought the name 
 of Bastiat. An ardent agitator for free trade and a popular pleader 
 for the existing order against the attacks of socialists and anarchists, 
 he was the author of numerous pamphlets, and at the time of his 
 death was engaged on a systematic treatise entitled Economic 
 Harmonies (Harmonies Economique), of which the first volume 
 only was completed. According to Bastiat, there is no such thing
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 671 
 
 as economic rent. Consequently, the landowner is not the recipi- 
 ent of an unearned income. What we call rent is simply a return 
 for past investments of capital. The profits on capital also, accord- 
 ing to him, are simply a return on past labor, and relatively towages, 
 a diminishing return. For it is a peculiarity of labor stored up in 
 those products which we call capital, that it continually diminishes 
 in value as compared with present labor. In other words, wages 
 are continually gaining relatively as compared with the profits of 
 capital. Capital may gain absolutely on account of the increase 
 in the amount of capital. Wages gain both absolutely and rela- 
 tively. Value gives us the ratio of exchange between services. 
 Economic gain is in proportion to economic service only that labor 
 is progressively a gainer on account of the fact that man's present 
 services (as seen in labor) increase in value as compared with 
 man's past services as accumulated in capital. To give a con- 
 crete illustration, the handle of an ax would be capital the re- 
 sult of stored-up past labor. It is likely to diminish in value con- 
 tinually when expressed in terms of present labor services, because 
 men are continually learning how to make better and better ax 
 handles. 
 
 As Bastiat denied the existence of pure economic rent in the 
 Ricardian sense, he also denied the Malthusian theory of popula- 
 tion, holding that no proof could be adduced of a tendency of popu- 
 lation to press upon the means of subsistence. The evils that we 
 experience come, according to Bastiat, from man's interference 
 with natural harmonies. Nature works things out well, and this 
 is the best of possible worlds if we would only let nature have her 
 way. 
 
 Henry C. Carey, the American contemporary of Bastiat, held 
 similar doctrines, and was apparently the more original man. If 
 either one borrowed from the other, it must have been Bastiat. 
 Probably neither one was guilty of any conscious plagiarism. 
 Carey, however, was not so good a representative of economic 
 optimism as Bastiat, because Carey believed that a protective 
 tariff was a necessity, and this implied the necessity of social action 
 to establish a system of economic harmonies. Carey's general 
 views otherwise are treated below.
 
 672 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 The writings of the optimists had a considerable influence for a 
 time in Germany, where they were developed and applied with 
 uncompromising logic by men like Prince-Smith, Faucher, and a 
 considerable number of others who were influential in the press 
 and practical affairs rather than in academic life. In the United 
 States these writings have had a great deal of influence upon a 
 number of early writers, among whom we may mention especially 
 the late Arthur Latham Perry, long professor in Williams College, 
 and Edward Atkinson, the well-known statistician and writer of 
 Boston. 
 
 Early American Economists. The reaction against the Eng- 
 lish economists, it is interesting to note, began earlier in the United 
 States than in England or Germany. In the early part of the 
 nineteenth century, emphatic dissent from the English doctrines was 
 voiced by a group of publicists, among whom may be mentioned 
 Alexander Hamilton, Daniel Raymond, Matthew Carey, Hezekiah 
 Niles, and Frederick List. Hamilton's work and views are well 
 known; Niles and Matthew Carey were pamphleteers of consider- 
 able note in the first third of the nineteenth century; and List, 
 who, in the view of some authorities, planted the seeds of the 
 German historical school, unquestionably obtained his distinctive 
 nationalistic views about political economy in the United States, 
 and first formulated them in his Outlines of American Political 
 Economy, published in 1827.* 
 
 Daniel Raymond, however, of all the American writers noted, 
 is the least known, and yet the author of the first American treatise 
 on political economy in which a distinctively American system of 
 economic thought is suggested. Raymond's first book, Thoughts 
 on Political Economy, appeared in 1820; a second edition, under 
 the title Elements of Political Economy, appeared in 1823, and the 
 latter was reprinted with slight changes in 1836 and 1840. The 
 essence of Raymond's system is found in his conception of wealth. 
 Wealth, he maintained, is not an aggregate of exchange values 
 but the opportunity to acquire the material comforts of life by 
 
 1 List returned to Germany and was there a forceful writer and agitator for 
 German unity, and is identified rather with the history of economic thought of 
 Germany than with that of the United States.
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 673 
 
 labor. The English political economy, in Raymond's view, was 
 a study of private as opposed to political or national economy. 
 Raymond emphasized the distinction between individual and 
 social wealth, and maintained that the laws of wealth laid down 
 by Adam Smith were untrue of a nation conceived as a unit. The 
 interests of particular individuals, or particular classes, he argued, 
 do not always coincide with the interests of the nation as a whole, 
 and the latter, he concluded, will be best advanced by developing 
 all the national powers to their widest possible extent. He was 
 thus a warm advocate of protection as opposed to laissez-faire. 
 
 Raymond's views had so impressed Matthew Carey that he 
 offered to support a chair of political economy at the University of 
 Maryland if the University would permit Raymond to fill it. Mat- 
 thew Carey's son, Henry C. Carey (1793-1879), by far the most 
 influential of the early American economists, was in like manner 
 probably influenced by the teachings of Raymond. Carey was 
 not only an earnest champion of protection, but an indefatigable 
 critic of classical economic doctrines. He denied the truth of 
 the Malthusian principle and the law of diminishing returns; 
 objected to the Ricardian theory of rent; and maintained that the 
 value of a commodity depends upon- the cost of reproduction 
 rather than the cost of production, as was laid down in the classi- 
 cal theory of value. Carey entertained a concept of wealth very 
 similar to that of Raymond, and in some parts of his work adopted 
 methods of investigation which brought him in close touch with 
 the sociologists and the German historical economists. The key- 
 stone of his economic system is the doctrine of association. The 
 increasing mastery of man over nature, or the increase of wealth, 
 Carey held to be dependent upon the increasing efficiency resulting 
 from a compact, homogeneous population, in which agriculture 
 and manufacture are conducted side by side, in which the home 
 market idea is carried out in the most complete way, and in which, 
 to be brief, the association of industrial and social units is most 
 intense and intimate. It can be readily understood why the eco- 
 nomic philosophy of Carey was so inimical to free trade at every 
 point. 
 
 The Austrian School. The protests against the classical econo- 
 
 91
 
 674 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 mists which we have been considering were directed largely 
 against the narrow scope and deductive methods of the classical 
 school. The Austrian economists represent a reaction not against 
 their methods, but against the conclusions, and particularly against 
 the theory of value of the classical school. The great contribution 
 of the Austrian school is the marginal utility theory of value which 
 has been most assiduously applied in economic analysis by a group 
 of Austrian economists, among whom may be mentioned Pro- 
 fessor Menger, Wieser, Sax, and Bohm-Bawerk. But the marginal 
 utility theory of value was advanced almost simultaneously, about 
 1871, by the English economist Jevons, the Austrian economist 
 Menger, and the Swiss economist Walras. 1 
 
 The Austrians have been a leading force in producing what is 
 not inaptly termed a renaissance in theory, although, as stated, 
 they indorsed the deductive and abstract methods of the classical 
 economists. The classical theory put the emphasis upon supply 
 or the conditions of supply, maintained that cost of production 
 determines value, and found the ultimate measure and explanation 
 of value in the pain and sacrifice of labor. The Austrians main- 
 tain that utility, the pleasure or satisfaction derived from con- 
 sumption, is the ultimate cause and measure of value; they empha- 
 size demand as the English economists emphasized supply; and 
 hold that value determines cost of production and not the cost 
 of production, value. Capital, they conclude, receives its value 
 from the finished product instead of giving value to that product. 
 The work of this school has tended to put the consumer in the place 
 primarily occupied by the capitalist as the center of discussion in 
 economic theory. 
 
 Present Condition of Economic Thought. The net effect of all 
 these protests against the classical English economists has been 
 to introduce a welcome catholicity into the methods of economic 
 investigation. The historical school emphasized the evolutionary 
 standpoint and the necessity of minute investigation of the facts 
 of industrial life, while the work of the Austrians operated to 
 
 1 In reality the marginal utility theory had been explained many years before 
 this by a number of obscure writers whose ideas, however, never affected the 
 main current of economic thought.
 
 HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 675 
 
 strengthen and explain the necessary place of deduction in eco- 
 nomic analysis. To-day the ordinary economist employs either 
 method, or both, as the subject-matter demands, and the contro- 
 versy about methods has become a thing of the past. With respect 
 to the theory of value, neither supply nor demand, neither cost nor 
 utility, neither the capitalist nor the consumer, is now said to exert 
 a predominating influence in the determination of values. The 
 Austrian school, it is now understood, supplied a needed correct- 
 ive without revolutionizing the earlier theory of value. The Aus- 
 trians themselves are seen to have been guilty of laying exaggerated 
 emphasis upon the consumer's influence upon value and price. 1 
 
 So, similarly, with respect to the scope of economics. The 
 attempt of the classical economists to isolate an "economic man" 
 ruled entirely by an enlightened self-interest and unaffected by 
 political, ethical, and humanitarian impulses, is recognized to have 
 been a mistake. But economics has never given itself to a com- 
 plete study of politics or ethics. It considers ethical and political 
 phenomena when these cannot be dissociated from economic 
 phenomena, but insists, nevertheless, upon the separation of eco- 
 nomics from ethics, politics, and sociology. We recognize that 
 these fields are not wholly or clearly differentiated, but we recog- 
 nize just as clearly that a division of labor is necessary if accurate 
 results are to be achieved. Furthermore, this division of labor is 
 showing itself progressively within the limits of economics itself, 
 as it has shown itself in all growing sciences. Indeed, the present 
 condition of economic thought was so accurately predicted by 
 Professor Jevons in 1876, that his words written in the midst of 
 the controversy among the adherents of the deductive, historical, 
 mathematical, and sociological methods of investigation may 
 well be employed to picture the condition of the science of eco- 
 nomics as it exists to-day: 
 
 "As I have previously explained, the present chaotic state of 
 economics arises from the confusing together of several branches 
 of knowledge. Subdivision is the remedy. We must distinguish 
 the empirical element from the abstract theory, from the applied 
 
 1 And there is reason to believe that their analysis was based in some degree 
 upon a faulty psychology.
 
 676 OUTLINES OF ECONOMICS 
 
 theory, and from the more detailed art of finance and administra- 
 tion. Thus will arise various sciences, such as commercial sta- 
 tistics, the mathematical theory of economics, systematic and 
 descriptive economics, economic sociology, and fiscal science. 
 There may even be a kind of cross subdivision of the sciences; 
 that is to say, there will be division into branches as regards the 
 subject, and division according to the manner of treating the 
 branch of the subject. The manner may be theoretical, empirical, 
 historical, or practical; the subject may be capital and labor, 
 currency, banking, taxation, land tenure, etc., not to speak of 
 the more fundamental division of the science as it treats of con- 
 sumption, production, exchange, and distribution of wealth. In 
 fact, the whole subject is so extensive, intricate, and diverse, that 
 it is absurd to suppose it can be treated in any single book, or in 
 any single manner." 1 
 
 QUESTIONS 
 
 What were the economic doctrines of the canonists? 
 How did the physiocrats differ from the mercantilists? 
 What is Adam Smith's relation to the physiocrats? 
 Characterize the "classical" school. 
 How did Ricardo use the Malthusian proposition ? 
 
 6. In what respect is Mill's thought a turning point in economic theory? 
 
 7. How is the socialist thought related to the theories of the classical 
 writers ? 
 
 8. In what did the protest of the historical school against the classical 
 school consist? 
 
 9. Characterize the economic thought of Bastiat? 
 
 10. What are the characteristics of the Austrian school? 
 
 REFERENCES 
 
 ASHLEY, W. J. Introduction to English Economic History and Theory. 
 CANNAN, E. History of Theories of Production and Distribution. 
 INGRAM, J. K. History of Political Economy. 
 PALGRAVE, R. H. I. Dictionary of Political Economy (articles on various 
 
 economists). 
 PRICE, L. L. History of Political Economy in England. 
 
 1 Jevons, Theory of Political Economy, 3d ed., pp. xv-rvi.
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 STATISTICS OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES 
 
 It will be observed that the payments in Table II are larger than in 
 Table I. This is because, as regards Table I, subtractions have been made 
 of certain items as follows : 
 
 (1) Payments on account of the public debt; 
 
 (2) premiums on bonds purchased and exchanged ; 
 
 (3) internal revenue and customs rebates and other funds ; 
 
 (4) interest on bonds of Pacific railroads ; 
 
 (5) District of Columbia expenditures (agency account) ; 
 
 (6) Soldiers' Home permanent fund (transfer). 
 
 The exclusion of these payments removes from the aggregate the greater 
 portion of those which under the census classification are designated tem- 
 porary and transfer. 
 
 Table III, giving the expenditures of the principal divisions of the United 
 States, helps us to understand the activities of the various main parts of 
 the United States as revealed in public expenditures ; and it also helps 
 us to understand the character and degree of evolution in the various 
 parts of the country, and the height to which civilization has ascended in 
 these parts, although here, again, the student must be cautioned that in 
 public expenditures we have only one of many indications of the nature 
 and growth of civilization, yet one of the most important. 
 
 North Atlantic division includes: New England and Southern North Atlantic 
 States. 
 
 New England includes: Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, Massachusetts, 
 Rhode Island, Connecticut. 
 
 Southern North Atlantic includes: New York, New Jersey, Pennsylvania. 
 
 Northern South Atlantic includes : Delaware, Maryland, District of Columbia, 
 Virginia, West Virginia. 
 
 Southern South Atlantic includes: North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, 
 Florida. 
 
 Eastern North Central includes : Ohio, Indiana, Illinois, Michigan, Wisconsin. 
 
 Western North Central includes: Minnesota, Iowa, Missouri, North Dakota, 
 South Dakota, Nebraska, Kansas. 
 
 Eastern South Central includes : Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, Mississippi. 
 
 Western South Central includes: Louisiana, Arkansas, Indian Territory, 
 Oklahoma, Texas. 
 
 Rocky Mountain includes: Montana, Idaho, Wycming, Colorado, New 
 Mexico. 
 
 Basin and Plateau includes: Arizona, Utah, Nevada. 
 
 Pacific includes : Washington, Oregon, California. 
 
 6 77
 
 6 7 8 
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 TABLE I 
 
 SUMMARY OF PAYMENTS FOR EXPENDITURES OF THE NATIONAL GOVERN- 
 MENT, STATES AND TERRITORIES, COUNTIES, CITIES, AND OTHER 
 MINOR CIVIL DIVISIONS OF CONTINENTAL UNITED STATES : 1902 
 
 GROSS PAYMENTS 
 
 Total 
 
 $1 Til O77 222 
 
 
 
 National government 
 
 6l7,=;'?O 137 
 
 States and territories 
 
 185 764 2O 2 
 
 Counties 
 
 IO7 2(Sc 827 
 
 Cities containing over 25,000 inhabitants 
 
 d68 6?7 7AO 
 
 Cities containing over 8000 and less than 25,000 inhabit- 
 ants 
 
 
 Other minor civil divisions (estimated) 
 
 222 082 884 
 
 
 
 Duplications amount to 
 
 
 Payments less duplications 
 
 $1 7O4 1 2O 060 
 

 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 679 
 
 TABLE II 
 
 PAYMENTS AND BALANCES OF THE NATIONAL GOVERNMENT FOR THE 
 YEAR ENDING JUNE 30, 1903 
 
 Total payments and balance on hand at close of year .... $2,566,878,140 
 
 Balance on hand at close of year 1,310,006,031 
 
 Total payments 1,256,872,109 
 
 Payments for : 
 
 Congress 4,764,578 
 
 Library of Congress 590,668 
 
 Executive departments 13,822,313 
 
 Foreign intercourse 3,204,522 
 
 Collection of internal revenue 4,496,479 
 
 Customs service 10,210,747 
 
 Government Printing Office 5,917,410 
 
 Judiciary 7>35.74 
 
 Territorial governments 261,591 
 
 Buildings and sites (outlays) 6,610,475 
 
 Military establishment 98,286,299 
 
 Naval establishment 55>95>93 
 
 Increase of the navy (outlays) 26,667,104 
 
 Life-saving service 1,746,841 
 
 Light-house establishment 4>537F3i6 
 
 Public Health and Marine-Hospital Service 1,356,456 
 
 Harbor and river improvements (outlays) 19,590,082 
 
 Indians 12,935,168 
 
 Pensions 138,425,646 
 
 Bureau of Animal Industry, Weather Bureau, and Agri- 
 cultural Investigation 4,536,426 
 
 Interest on public debt 28,556,169 
 
 Postal service, including Post Office Department 139,134,510 
 
 Mints and assay offices 1,456,221 
 
 Bureau of Engraving and Printing 2,782,348 
 
 Public debt 605,641,539 
 
 Premiums on bonds purchased and exchanged 10,907,120 
 
 Internal revenue and customs rebates and other refunds 16,881,955 
 
 Interest on bonds of Pacific railroads 180 
 
 Grants to District of Columbia 3,415,999 
 
 District of Columbia expenditures (agency account) .. . 5,168,039 
 
 Soldiers' Home permanent fund (transfer) 743> Z 39 
 
 Miscellaneous 20,923,099
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 S S 
 
 K u 
 
 W 
 
 "S O 
 
 oo OQ >o M ts. 
 
 & 
 
 t^> M O 
 
 O~ 10 of 
 
 S O 
 3 > 
 
 O rg O >-Oo 
 
 rj- >~, rf> 00 
 rf w~, 00 NO 
 
 00 O O ON 
 
 O>O\OO w 
 
 O O^ 
 
 OO f^ 
 
 CX 00_ O_ i^-, 00_ ^ *-i O; N_ tx. fO * >o 
 
 I s * ^ ^ t\ ^ *O N^j 
 
 ON 00 M. CK M rf) w 
 N ** nl tf) O> ^, ^ 
 
 2; Q 
 
 gw 
 
 Sg 
 
 Es 
 
 u-oo 
 ' ' 
 
 3 ! 
 
 w 'r 
 
 lllllllllllllllllll
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 68l 
 
 
 j 
 
 eiSJ83Jl*l!l!lS|?E 1 
 
 
 
 u 
 
 Q 
 
 ?t 3 S^ >& 11"^ 2 > 5'1 S *" 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 S 
 
 
 
 3& "S^- ***<%* 
 
 
 
 a 
 
 il*5|5SSS-83l^?!41l8i 
 
 
 ITURES 
 
 * 
 
 9J 
 
 ||!|lff|pl?!l H !"" 
 
 
 :XPENE 
 
 H 
 
 lilSl5l?:f|-^^?f|* 
 
 
 M 
 
 o 
 
 (X 
 
 M 
 
 O 
 
 U 
 
 J? ^" M N 
 
 1 
 
 1 
 
 AYME> 
 
 3 I 
 8 E 
 
 3i?^S*5?S 85^4885 
 
 D 
 
 OH 
 
 g J ! 
 
 ^i^t^OO ^f ^ vj w O^tCvow rf rO'fvOOO 
 
 s 
 
 
 4* v 
 
 S |-2 
 g S 
 
 o 
 
 *^*V..._; : *.".! 
 
 
 
 .S 
 
 
 O 
 
 < u w 
 
 1 |1 
 
 SilSf s5.?&?ggJi4l 
 
 S 
 
 
 H 8 
 
 O Jj y 
 
 ST3 
 C 
 
 E rt 
 
 o >/; M * <\T M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 w.-o-o 
 
 
 
 H 
 
 C/3 
 
 w 1 J J 1 -1 11 J S 2 : : : 
 
 TJ '5 ^ -2 ~j -s -S c a . c c : 
 
 
 
 DIVISIONS 
 UNITED 
 

 
 682 
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 PAYMENTS FOR EXPENDITURES 
 
 OTHER HIGHWAY 
 EXPENDITURES 
 
 t^ so 
 
 ? 5- 
 
 Tf P 
 
 ^f* ON 
 c\i 00 
 
 to GO 
 
 O NO 
 
 * M 
 
 sO ON 
 
 fM t^ 
 
 , ON 
 
 to ON 
 *~" C 
 
 HI Oo 
 
 i~- ON 
 
 Tf IO 
 
 ^* w 
 
 
 ON Tf 
 
 o 
 ^. 
 
 M h*, 
 
 to sO OQ r HI w^ 
 * PO so t^ ON o, 
 CO_ * Oo Os 00_ \j- 
 HI Lr) so" PI PO c\j 
 
 O * 
 to ON 
 
 ON P* 
 
 M HI 
 
 o? 2> 
 
 p? ^ 
 jf 
 
 ON M 
 00 CO 
 
 HI 
 
 sO O 
 ^" t^ 
 so" 
 
 SO 
 
 00 
 
 STREET 
 LIGHTING 
 
 M (M 
 
 O IO 
 
 PO ON 
 
 Ix. OO 
 
 PO o 
 a GO 
 ^ 
 
 00 to 
 
 Jx. so 
 
 Q <N 
 
 CS) M 
 
 00 <5- 
 O Xi 
 
 O CO 
 
 Jt 
 sO 
 00 
 
 a 
 
 o 
 
 ON 
 PO 
 
 0> s" 
 
 ftf 
 
 PI ci 
 
 to * 
 
 PO 00" 
 
 Os sO 
 (\) to 
 
 PI tx* 
 ^ W~> 
 
 M to On so PI Oo 
 Pi PI tx. 'O HI so 
 to O o u-> \r> ^ 
 
 PI so 
 PI l~ 
 
 ON 
 
 sO 
 
 SEWERS, DRAINAGE, 
 AND OTHER 
 SANITATION 
 
 Ol (Nl 
 
 PO o 
 r^. to 
 
 Oo <M 
 Irs, 00 
 
 sO GO 
 
 IO PO 
 
 t^*> M 
 
 Oo * 
 (\1 O 
 
 T}- f*1 OC 00 
 
 PI t^ 
 
 Pi" rf 
 00 rr 
 to 
 
 ON 
 
 ON 
 CS 
 
 Er ; 
 
 sO ON 
 
 f :- 
 
 Jo 
 
 00 <M 
 ON OO 
 
 o PO 
 
 ^ H? 
 
 s> 
 
 K. ? 
 
 & 
 
 N - tx. 
 
 HI 
 
 HEALTH 
 CONSERVATION 
 
 Oo 
 10 Os 
 
 PI to 
 
 00 M 
 
 ^)" to 
 
 PSI so 
 
 Os M 
 
 ON Oo 
 to c\) 
 
 PO IO 
 
 00 Tf 
 
 t^* so 
 
 Oo 1^ 
 
 10 GO 
 to Ov 
 
 HI CS) 
 
 PO 00 
 
 PO HI 
 HI 10 
 
 sO 
 
 M 
 
 SO ~ 
 
 & * 
 
 N L 
 
 OQ N 
 
 so ^ 
 
 IN" 
 
 t^* sO 
 ON *~ 
 
 K, IO SO SO 
 
 ? J^R 
 
 IO HI 
 
 PO to 
 
 ON PI 
 ^ M 
 
 HI 
 
 MISCELLANEOUS 
 PROTECTION TO 
 LIFE AND 
 PROPERTY 
 
 o *^ 
 
 10 N, 
 
 to so 
 
 Ov * 
 
 M OQ IO PO 
 
 tO PT} SO ~ 
 
 tx to 
 
 PO oo 
 
 O H 
 to >t 
 
 sO PO 
 
 00 Tf 
 
 \O t"- 
 
 OO 
 sO 
 
 
 10 ^f 
 
 1-1 PI 
 PO IO 
 t~- to 
 
 M 
 
 N J^~ 
 
 tx. 
 
 so PI 
 ON N 
 
 -T o 
 H '^f' 
 
 H 
 
 O xns 
 t~- O 
 
 O\ t^ 1 * 
 
 CO 
 PO 
 
 DIVISIONS OF THE 
 UNITED STATES 
 
 
 Continental United States . . 
 
 North Atlantic division. . . . 
 
 New England 
 Southern North Atlantic . . . 
 
 South Atlantic division. . . . 
 Northern South Atlantic... 
 
 Southern South Atlantic... 
 North Central division 
 
 Eastern North Central 
 Western North Central .... 
 
 South Central division 
 Eastern South Central 
 
 
 
 
 
 i : 
 
 
 
 
 Western South Ct 
 Western division 
 
 Rocky Mountain 
 Basin and Plateai 
 
 Pacific 
 Hawaii ' 
 
 O 
 
 _u
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 68 3 
 
 
 n 
 
 S3|?g 
 
 OOOO">/1oCTi>-if^o*<>-'*OOO 
 
 
 
 2 < 
 |g 
 
 51 
 
 M X? Io O 5 "% 
 M 
 
 11 lotsoooo o f oo'xa' i '>M c^oo 
 
 OQOoOO^'^ctOOoOi-'OO'O 
 
 
 
 
 
 SII-sS 
 
 SJISSIySSS???^ 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 M -^. CO i-t l^j 
 
 O^ 00 ^^ to *"O (\i ^ ITJ Qo O\ 00 O **3 CO 
 
 
 a 
 3 
 
 13 
 
 H 
 
 Q 
 
 H 
 
 i &s 
 
 N 
 
 
 PENDI 
 
 1 
 
 3 1,1 S & 
 
 SS^H1,%l?s4?iS 
 
 
 x 
 to 
 
 i 
 
 CK P 
 
 M v ^ 
 
 f xs ^t. "2 ts. 
 
 s s ^ s> S ^ & ? ^ f ^ 1 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 1 
 1 
 
 H 
 H 
 
 9 
 
 
 t* O O O ^^i 
 
 N XS ^t- "i Oo 
 
 
 1 
 & 
 
 ?, 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 M (^ * CO O~ 
 
 fO rC fO vd" c\T 
 
 M ^^ 
 
 !*!l!|!^*--t* 
 
 Jed in contin 
 
 
 2 
 
 n ts. M_ <5 x^ 
 
 sfcsssmsigs&gs 
 
 1 
 1 
 
 
 9 
 
 1 ^ 2 ^. 
 
 o\ o OQ ^ ^* ^ ^o *^ *"^ o ^ ^ o ^o 
 
 
 
 
 
 in ri~ i-i 
 
 * " ^ M ^ ^ N 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 (i 
 
 a 
 t- 
 
 i 
 
 5 C/3 
 
 
 
 
 b 
 | 
 
 ) 
 | 
 
 f- 
 
 UNITED STAT 
 
 Continental United Statt 
 North Atlantic division 
 New England 
 Southern North Atlant 
 South Atlantic division 
 
 || 1 1 1 1 1 1 ; ; : 
 
 fit fit i if 1 s -. 
 
 I,- ^. f * 8 w *9 ** 5 -y 
 
 1 | 1 1 1 1|| 1 1 1| 1 1 

 
 684 
 
 APPENDIX A 
 
 W " 
 
 > x 
 
 z W 
 
 SM fc 
 OOO 11 
 O ^^0 
 
 " R 
 
 5 28 
 
 O<^0 OvOOOQOOvC f^GC 
 - 
 
 O On 
 
 o T<\I t^T 
 O\O t^rOrOro M 
 >H\O O>*-iOOXi O 
 
 fa < 
 O H 
 
 S 
 
 w 
 
 Z Q 
 
 O W 
 
 oo S 
 >g 
 S 
 
 O'UO 
 
 ' 
 
 ' - 
 
 Illllllllllllllllll
 
 APPENDIX B 
 
 SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY, COURSES OF READING, AND 
 SUBJECTS FOR ESSAYS, DISCUSSIONS, AND DEBATES 
 
 SOME teachers of political economy supplement text-book work 
 by assigned reading chiefly; others rely on questions, exercises, 
 and brief reports in connection with specific subjects taken up in 
 the class; others again prefer that the student write one or two 
 longer essays for the whole course. In this book specific references, 
 questions, and exercises have been provided in connection with 
 each chapter, and in this appendix are given subjects for the longer 
 essays. In most cases it will be desirable to limit the topics sug- 
 gested, and each subject will suggest a number of similar ones. 
 Usually the teacher will desire to make his own list adapted to the 
 needs of his students, but the list here given will in many cases be 
 of convenience where classes are large. 
 
 On methods of teaching political economy, the following refer- 
 ences will be found of help: 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Education, Vol. XI, p. 539. 
 
 CLOW, F. Economic Studies (American Economic Association), 1899. 
 
 DIXON, F. H. School Review, January, 1898. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Educational Review, Vol. 20, p. 152. 
 
 HOXIE, R. F. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. IX, p. 481. 
 
 LAUGHLIN, J. L. The Study of Political Economy, New York, 1885; also 
 
 Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 9, p. 384, and Atlantic Monthly, 
 
 May, 1896. 
 
 COMMONS, J. R. The Inland Educator, December, 1895. 
 THURSTON, H. W. School Review, Vol. 4, p. 604. 
 
 SUBJECTS FOR ESSAYS, DISCUSSIONS, AND DEBATES 
 i. THEORETICAL 
 
 I? the Supply of Land Limited ? 
 Is Abstinence one of the Costs of Production ? 
 
 685
 
 686 APPENDIX B 
 
 Possible Substitutes for Competition. 
 
 One Hundred Definitions of Capital. 
 
 Can Mere Mass of Capital be the Basis of Monopoly Power? 
 
 The Wage-fund Theory. 
 
 The Balance of Trade Theory. 
 
 2. BIOGRAPHICAL AND PERSONAL 
 
 John Law and his Schemes. 
 
 Robert Owen. 
 
 Rousseau and his Social Philosophy. 
 
 Sketch of the life of Adam Smith. 
 
 Sketch of the life of J. S. Mill. 
 
 Richard Cobden. 
 
 Ferdinand Lasalle. 
 
 Josiah Warren. 
 
 Types of Modern Business Men. 
 
 3. MONEY 
 
 The Production of Gold since 1850. 
 
 The Per capita Supply of Money in the United States. 
 
 The Campaign of 1896. 
 
 The Latin Monetary Union. 
 
 The International Monetary Conferences. 
 
 Substitutes for Gold as a Standard of Value. 
 
 Illustrations of Gresham's Law. 
 
 Paper Money in the Colonies. 
 
 The Establishment of the United States Coinage System. 
 
 French Assignats. 
 
 4. BANKING 
 
 Failures among our National Banks. 
 
 The New York Safety Fund System. 
 
 Insurance of Bank Deposits. 
 
 Branch Banking. 
 
 Asset Currency. 
 
 The Origin of our National Banking System. 
 
 The Control of Trust Companies. 
 
 The Bank of England. 
 
 The Bank of France. 
 
 The German Imperial Bank. 
 
 The Canadian Banking System. 
 
 Usury and Usury Laws. 
 
 Postal Savings Banks.
 
 APPENDIX H 687 
 
 5. THE LABOR MOVEMENT 
 
 Old Age Pensions. 
 
 Compulsory Arbitration. 
 
 Employers' Liability for Accidents. 
 
 Employment Offices. 
 
 Shall the Boycott be Legalized? 
 
 Should Injunctions be prohibited in Labor Disputes? 
 
 Should Trades Unions enter Politics? 
 
 The Statistics of Strikes. 
 
 The Trend of Wages. 
 
 Insurance against Unemployment. 
 
 Employers' Associations. 
 
 The Premium System of Wage Payment. 
 
 Trade Agreements. 
 
 The Business Management of the . . . Union. 
 
 Should Trades Unions Incorporate? 
 
 The Workingman's Attitude toward Piece Work. 
 
 The Present Status of Child Labor Legislation. 
 
 The American Federation of Labor. 
 
 Systems of Apprenticeship. 
 
 Industrial Education. 
 
 Eight-hour Legislation. 
 
 6. INSURANCE 
 
 The Beginnings of Insurance in England. 
 
 Life Insurance in the United States before 1880. 
 
 Varieties of Life Insurance Policies. 
 
 Mortality Tables. 
 
 Joint Life Insurance. 
 
 The Surplus of Life Insurance Companies. 
 
 Surrender Values. 
 
 Investments of Insurance Companies. 
 
 Expense Loading in Life Insurance Premiums. 
 
 State Insurance in New Zealand. 
 
 Insurance Legislation in the State of New York. 
 
 Fraternal Insurance. 
 
 Industrial Insurance in the United States. 
 
 Workmen's Insurance in Germany. 
 
 Employers' Liability Insurance. 
 
 Workmen's Collective Insurance. 
 
 Rate Making in Fire Insurance. 
 
 Marine Insurance.
 
 688 APPENDIX B 
 
 7. TRANSPORTATION 
 
 History of the Erie Canal. 
 
 Economic Significance of the Panama Canal. 
 
 The Improvement of the Mississippi River. 
 
 The Granger Movement. 
 
 Railroad Pools. 
 
 Federal Safety Appliance Legislation. 
 
 Financial History of the . . . Railway Company. 
 
 Present Status of Railway Consolidation. 
 
 Methods of Railway Consolidation. 
 
 Uniform Freight Classifications. 
 
 Rate-making Powers of State Railroad Commissions. 
 
 The Interstate Commerce Act and its Amendments. 
 
 The Long and Short Haul Clause. 
 
 The Basing Point System. 
 
 Group Rates. 
 
 Expense as a Basis for Rate Making. 
 
 The Northern Securities Company. 
 
 8. CORPORATIONS 
 
 Varieties of Stocks and Bonds. 
 
 The Prices of the Stocks and Bonds of the . . . Company since 1900 
 
 Federal License or Federal Incorporation ? 
 
 History of the Standard Oil Company. 
 
 The Organization of the United States Steel Corporation. 
 
 The Control of Corporations in Massachusetts. 
 
 The International Mercantile Marine Company. 
 
 The Basis of Capitalization. 
 
 9. MONOPOLIES AND TRUSTS 
 
 Monopolies in Ancient and Mediaeval Times. 
 
 Monopolies in Seventeenth Century England. 
 
 The History of the Whisky Trust. 
 
 Control of Raw Material as a Source of Monopoly Power. 
 
 The Economies of Combination. 
 
 Effects of Trusts on Prices. 
 
 The Tariff and the Sugar Trust. 
 
 Trusts in England at the Present Time. 
 
 German Cartells. 
 
 Patents as a Basis of Monopoly Power. 
 
 The Telegraph in England. 
 
 Concentration in Banking.
 
 APPENDIX B 689 
 
 10. INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 Customs Duties in Colonial Times. 
 
 The Dingley Tariff Act. 
 
 Customs Regulations of the Treasury Department. 
 
 History of the Tariff on Wool. 
 
 The Australian Tariff Policy. 
 
 The Revival of Protectionism in England. 
 
 The Tin Plate Industry. 
 
 The Civil War and the Tariff. 
 
 A Tariff Commission. 
 
 Reciprocity. 
 
 Sources of our Leading Imports. 
 
 The Destination of our Leading Exports. 
 
 n. PUBLIC FINANCE 
 
 Federal Income Taxes. 
 
 Taxation of Inheritances in the United States. 
 
 The Assessment of Real Estate. 
 
 Franchise Taxes in New York. 
 
 License Fees in the Southern States. 
 
 Taxation of Railroads in the United States. 
 
 The Taxation of Banks. 
 
 The Taxation of Insurance Companies. 
 
 Mortgage Taxation. 
 
 Segregation of State and Local Revenues. 
 
 Federal Expenditure for Army and Navy. 
 
 Our Pension System. 
 
 12. MISCELLANEOUS 
 
 The Attempt in Germany to Control Stock Exchange Speculation. 
 
 International Sugar Conventions. 
 
 Municipal Ownership in Great Britain. 
 
 Famines in India. 
 
 Development of Scientific Forestry in the Utiited States. 
 
 Causes for the Decline in the Birth Rate. 
 
 The English Cooperative Movement. 
 
 Methods of Charitable Relief. 
 
 Future of our Coal Supply. 
 
 Shipping Subsidies. 
 
 BIBLIOGRAPHY AND COURSES OF READING 
 
 The first five books under each division of the bibliography are 
 recommended as an introductory course of study in that particular
 
 690 APPENDIX B 
 
 subject. The student should become familiar with the apparatus 
 which a modern library provides for finding what has been written 
 upon the subject he is investigating. The card catalogue and the 
 cumulative book and periodical indexes need hardly be mentioned. 
 The documents of the federal government contain a vast amount of 
 important economic material. Thorough indexes of this material 
 have been prepared, and a monthly catalogue is issued by the 
 Superintendent of Documents, at a price of $1.10 per year. An 
 index of the economic material in the documents of the separate 
 states is being prepared under the direction of the department of 
 economics and sociology of the Carnegie Institution of Washing- 
 ton, volumes for five states having been issued or put in press. 
 
 i. GENERAL ECONOMIC THEORY 
 
 MARSHALL, ALFRED. Principles of Economics, 5th ed., London and New 
 
 York, 1907. 
 
 CARVER, T. N. Distribution of Wealth, New York, 1904. 
 BOHM-BAWERK, E. VON. Positive Theory of Capital (trans, by W. Smart), 
 
 London, 1891. 
 
 CLARK, J. B. Distribution of Wealth, New York, 1899. 
 DAVENPORT, H. J. Value and Distribution, Chicago, 1908. 
 HOBSON, J. A. Economics of Distribution, New York, 1900. 
 HADLEY, A. T. Economics, New York, 1897. 
 FISHER, IRVING. The Nature of Capital and Income, New York, 1906. 
 
 The Rate of Interest, New York, 1907. 
 FETTER, F. A. Principles of Economics, New York, 1904. 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Selected Readings in Economics, Boston, 1907. 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Wages and Capital, New York, 1896. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Principles of Economics, 3d ed., New York, 1907. 
 SEAGER, H. R. Introduction to Economics, 3d ed., New York, 1905. 
 HAWLEY, F. B. Enterprise and the Productive Process, New York, 1907. 
 
 2. HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT 
 
 SMITH, ADAM. A n Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of 
 Nations, edited by E. Cannan, 2 vols., London, 1904. 
 
 INGRAM, J. K. History of Political Economy, 2d ed., New York, 1907. 
 
 RICARDO, DAVID. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, London, 
 1817. 
 
 MILL, J. S. Principles of Political Economy, London, 1848. 
 
 CANNAN, EDWIN. History of Theories of Production and Distribution, 2d 
 ed. r London, 1903.
 
 APPENDIX B 691 
 
 SENIOR, NASSAU. Political Economy, London, 1872. 
 
 CAIRNES, J. E. Leading Principles of Political Economy, New York, 1874. 
 MALTHUS, T. R. Principles of Political Economy, ad ed., London, 1836. 
 JEVONS, W. S. The Theory of Political Economy, London, 3d ed., 1888. 
 BOHM-BAWERK, E. VON. Capital and Interest (trans, by W. Smart), London, 
 
 1890. Recent Literature on Interest (trans, by Scott and Feilbogen), 
 
 New York, 1903. 
 
 CAREY, H. C. Principles of Political Economy, ad ed., New York, 1907. 
 HIGGS, HENRY. The Physiocrats, London, 1897. 
 SCHMOLLER, GUSTAV. The Mercantile System (trans, by W. J. Ashley), New 
 
 York, 1896. 
 GEORGE, HENRY. Progress and Poverty (4th ed., 1880), reprinted New York, 
 
 1904. 
 
 3. ECONOMIC HISTORY 
 
 BOG ART, ERNEST L. Economic History of the United States, New York, 1908. 
 COMAN, KATHERINE. The Industrial History of the United States, New 
 
 York, 1905. 
 CUNNINGHAM, WILLIAM. Growth of English Industry and Commerce, 3 vols., 
 
 Cambridge, 1903 and 1905. 
 
 TURNER, F. J. Rise of the New West, New York, 1906. 
 UNWIN, GEORGE. Industrial Organization in the i6th and ijth Centuries, 
 
 Oxford, 1904. 
 WEEDEN, VV. B. Economic and Social History of New England, Boston and 
 
 New York, 1891. 
 
 BRUCE, P. H. Economic History of Virginia, 2 vols., New York, 1896. 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. The Economic Interpretation of History, New York, 
 
 1902. 
 
 DAY, CLIVE. History of Commerce, New York, 1908. 
 BUCHER, C. Industrial Evolution (trans, by S. M. Wickett), New York, 
 
 1901. 
 
 HOBSON, J. A. Evolution of Modern Capitalism, 2d ed., New York, 1908. 
 ASHLEY, W. J. English Economic History, 2 vols., New York, 1893 and 
 
 1894. 
 
 4. THE LABOR MOVEMENT 
 
 ADAMS, T. S., and SUMNER, H. L. Labor Problems, New York, 1905. 
 
 WEBB, SIDNEY and BEATRICE. Industrial Democracy, 2d ed., London, 
 New York, and Bombay, 1902. 
 
 HOLLANDER, J. H., and BARNETT, G. E. Studies in American Trade Union- 
 ism, New York, 1906. 
 
 COMMONS, J. R. Trade Unionism and Labor Problems, Boston, 1905. 
 
 HUTCHINS, B. L., and HARRISON, A. A History of Factory Legislation, 
 2d ed., London, 1907. 
 
 CLARK, VICTOR S. The Labor Movement in Australia, New York, 1906.
 
 692 APPENDIX B 
 
 KELLEY, FLORENCE. Some Ethical Gains through Legislation, New York, 
 
 1905. 
 
 BOOTH, CHARLES. Old Age Pensions and the Aged Poor, London, 1907. 
 ROBERTS, PETER. Anthracite Coal Communities, New York, 1904. 
 BUCHANAN, J. R. The Story of a Labor Agitator, New York, 1903. 
 MORE, L. B. Wage-Earner's Budgets, New York, 1907. 
 
 5. PLANS FOR SOCIAL REFORM 
 
 ELY, R. T. Socialism and Social Reform, New York, 1905. 
 
 KIRKUP, THOMAS. History of Socialism, ad ed., London, 1900. 
 
 ENSOR, R. C. K. Modern Socialism, London, 1907. 
 
 ELTZBACHER, PAUL. Anarchism (trans, by S. T. Byington), London, 
 
 1908. 
 
 JAURES, J. L. Studies in Socialism (trans, by M. Minturn), New York, 1906. 
 PODMORE, FRANK. The Life of Robert Owen, 2 vols., London, 1907. 
 BROOKS, J. G. The Social Unrest, New York, 1903. 
 MARX, KARL. Capital (trans, by E. Unterman), 3 vols., Chicago, 1906. 
 MARX, KARL, and FRIEDRICH ENGELS. The Communist Manifesto, many 
 
 editions. 
 
 HUNTER, ROBERT. Socialists at Work, New York, 1908. 
 HOLYOAKE, G. J. History of Cooperation, new ed., 2 vols., New York, 
 
 1906. 
 
 6. CORPORATIONS, MONOPOLIES, AND TRUSTS 
 
 MEADE, E. S. Trust Finance, New York, 1903. 
 
 RIPLEY, W. Z. Trusts, Pools, and Corporations, Boston, 1905. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Monopolies and Trusts, New York, 1900. 
 
 HIRST, F. W. Monopolies, Trusts, and Cartells, London, 1905. 
 
 TARBELL, IDA M. History of the Standard Oil Company, New York, 1904. 
 
 CLARK, J. B. The Problem of Monopoly, New York, 1904. 
 
 PRICE, W. H. English Patents of Monopoly, Boston, 1906. 
 
 Bureau of Corporations, Report on the Petroleum Industry, 2 vols., 
 
 Washington, 1907 and 1908. 
 
 MEYER, H. R. Municipal Ownership in Great Britain, New York, 1906. 
 HOWE, F. C. The British City, New York, 1907. 
 VEBLEN, T. B. The Theory of Business Enterprise, New York, 1904. 
 
 7. TRANSPORTATION 
 
 JOHNSON, E. R. American Railway Transportation, 2d ed., New York, 
 1905. Ocean and Inland Water Transportation, New York, 1906. 
 
 RIPLEY, W. Z. Railway Problems, Boston, 1907. 
 
 BEALE, J. H. B., and WYMAN, B. Law of Railroad Rate Regulation, Boston, 
 1906.
 
 APPENDIX B 693 
 
 " American Waterways." A nnals of the American Academy of Political and 
 
 Social Science, January, 1908. 
 
 ACWORTH, WILLIAM. Elements of Railway Economics, Oxford, 1905. 
 PHILLIPS, U. B. History of Transportation in the Eastern Cotton Belt, 
 
 New York, 1908. 
 
 MERRITT, A. N. Federal Regulation of Railway Rates, Boston, 1907. 
 MEEKER, R. History of Shipping Subsidies, New York, 1905. 
 NOYES, W. C. American Railroad Rales, Boston, 1905. 
 W T EBB, W. L. Economics of Railroad Construction, New York, 1906. 
 
 8. INTERNATIONAL TRADE 
 
 FISK, G. M. International Commercial Policies, New York, 1907. 
 TAUSSIG, F. W. Tariff History of the United States, sth ed., New York, 
 
 1903. 
 
 BASTABLE, C. F. Theory of International Trade, London, 1897. 
 SMART, WILLIAM. Return to Protection, 2d ed., London, 1906. 
 CLARE, GEORGE. The A B C of the Foreign Exchanges, London, 1895. 
 MARGRAFF, A. W. International Exchange, ad ed., Chicago, 1904. 
 BOWLEY, A. L. England's Foreign Trade in the Nineteenth Century, 2d 
 
 ed., London, 1905. 
 STANWOOD, EDWARD. American Tariff Controversies in the Nineteenth 
 
 Century, 2 vols., Boston, 1903. 
 HOBSON, J. A. International Trade, London, 1904. 
 FUCHS, K. J. The Trade Policy of Great Britain and Her Colonies since 
 
 1860 (trans, by Archibald), London, 1905. 
 ROOT, J. W. Colonial Tariffs, Liverpool, 1006. 
 CUNNINGHAM, WILLIAM. The Free Trade Movement, 2d ed., Cambridge, 
 
 1905. 
 
 9. INSURANCE 
 
 DAWSON, M. M. Elements of Life Insurance, 2d ed., New York, 1902. The 
 
 Business Side of Life Insurance, New York, 1905. 
 MOIR, HENRY. Life Assurance Primer, New York, 1904. 
 KITCHIN, F. H. Principles and Finance of Fire Insurance, London, 1904. 
 Yale Insurance Lectures, New Haven, 2 vols., 1904. 
 Gow, WILLIAM. Marine Insurance, London, 1900. 
 Institutes of Actuaries Text-book, 2 vols., 2d ed., London, 1902. 
 W T AMBAUGH, EUGENE. Cases on Insurance, Cambridge, 1902. 
 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, special 
 
 volume on Insurance, Philadelphia, Vol. 26, 1905. 
 "Q. P." How to buy Life Insurance, New York, 1906. 
 New York Legislative Investigating Committee, 7 vols., 1905.
 
 694 APPENDIX B 
 
 10. MONEY AND BANKING 
 
 SCOTT, W. A. Money and Banking, 2d ed., New York, 1908. 
 
 HULL, W. H. Practical Problems in Banking and Commerce, New York, 
 
 1907. 
 
 EASTON, H. T. Money, Exchange, and Banking, London, 1905. 
 LAUGHLIN, J. L. Principles of Money, Chicago, 1903. 
 JOHNSON, J. F. Money and Currency, Boston, 1906. 
 KINLEY, DAVID. Money, New York, 1904. 
 WHITE, HORACE. Money and Banking, New York, 1902. 
 SHAW, W. A. History of the Currency, 3d ed., New York, 1896. 
 CLEVELAND, F. A. The Bank and the Treasury, New York, 1905. 
 CONANT, C. A. Modern Banks of Issue, ad ed., New York, 1896. 
 WILLIS, H. P. A History of the Latin Monetary Union, Chicago, 1901. 
 RUSSELL, H. B. International Monetary Conferences, New York, 1898. 
 
 ii. AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS 
 
 TAYLOR, H. C. Introduction to the Study of Agricultural Economics, New 
 
 York, 1905. 
 
 COLLIN. The New Agriculture, New York, 1907. 
 PRICHARD, NEWELL, and PINCHOT. Report of Public Land Commission, 
 
 Washington. 
 
 HAGGARD, H. R. Rural England, z vols., New York, 1902. 
 ROGERS, A. G. L. The Business Side of Agriculture, London, 1004. 
 HIBBARD, B. H. History of Agriculture in Dane County, Wisconsin, 
 
 Madison, 1904. 
 Census Reports. 
 
 Publications of the United States Department of Agriculture. 
 BRIGHT, JOHN. The Agricultural Valuer's Assistant, London, 1901. 
 HALL, BOLTON. Three Acres and Liberty, New York, 1907. 
 
 12. STATISTICS 
 
 BOWLEY, A. L. Elements of Statistics, 2d ed., London, 1902. 
 
 MAYO SMITH, RICHMOND. Statistics and Economics, New York, 1899; 
 
 Statistics and Sociology, New York, 1895. 
 NEWSHOLME, ARTHUR. Vital Statistics, 3d ed., London, 1899. 
 THORNDIKE, E. L. An Introduction to the Theory of Mental and Social 
 
 Measurements, New York, 1904. 
 BAILEY, W. B. Modern Social Conditions, New York, 1906. 
 
 13. MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS 
 
 FISHER, IRVING. Brief Introduction to Infinitesimal Calculus, 3d ed., New 
 York, 1906.
 
 APPENDIX B 695 
 
 COURNOT, A. A. Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth, trans, 
 by N. T. Bacon, with a bibliography of Mathematical Economics by 
 Irving Fisher, New York, 1897. 
 
 14. PUBLIC FINANCE 
 
 ADAMS, H. C. The Science of Finance, New York, 1809. 
 
 BASTABLE, C. F. Public Finance, 2d ed., London, 1895. 
 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Essays in Taxation, New York, 3d ed., New York, 
 1000. The Shifting and Incidence of Taxation, New York, 2d ed., 
 New York, 1899. 
 
 DEWEY, D. R. Financial History of the United States, New York, 1903. 
 
 BULLOCK, C. J. Selected Readings in Public Finance, Boston, 1906. 
 
 COOLEY, T. M. A Treatise on the Law of Taxation, 3d ed., 188. 
 
 ELY, R. T. Taxation in American States and Cities, New York, 1888. 
 
 SELIGMAN, E. R. A. Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, Balti- 
 more, 1894. 
 
 ADAMS, H. C. Public Debts, New York, 1890. 
 
 SCOTT, W. A. The Repudiation of State Debts, New York, 1893. 
 
 Twelfth Census Reports on Wealth, Debt, and Taxation. 
 
 15. ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 
 
 TROTTER, The Geography of Commerce, New York, 1903. 
 DAY, CLIVE. The History of Commerce, New York, 1908. 
 REDWAY, J. W. Commercial Geography, New York, 1903. 
 ADAMS, C. C. A Text-book of Commercial Geography, New York, 1901. 
 CHISHOLM, G. G. A Handbook of Commercial Geography, 4th ed., New 
 York, 1903. 
 
 16. DICTIONARIES AND REFERENCE BOOKS 
 
 PALGRAVE, H. I. Dictionary of Political Economy. 
 
 BLISS, W. D. P. Encyclopedia of Social Reform (zd ed.). 
 
 LALOR, J. J. Encyclopedia of Political Science, Political Economy, and 
 
 United States History. 
 New International Encyclopcedia.. 
 Statistical Abstract of the United States. 
 Social Progress: A Year Book (edited by J. Strong). 
 
 PERIODICALS 
 
 Quarterly Journal of Economics (Boston). 
 
 Journal of Political Economy (Chicago). 
 
 Yale Review (New Haven). 
 
 Publications and Bulletin of the American Economic Association. 
 
 The Economic Journal (London). 
 
 Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (London). 
 
 Quarterly Publications of the American Statistical Association.
 
 INDEX 
 
 Abstinence, 96. See Waiting. 
 Agriculture, development, 37, 46, 75; 
 
 problems, 528; stage, 33. 
 Aldrich Act, 1908, 261. 
 American people, characteristics, 58. 
 Amortization of taxes, 621. 
 Anarchism, 525. 
 Anti-trust Act, 88, 153. 
 Arbitration, 402 et seq. 
 Asset banking, 261. 
 Authority, 27. 
 Averages, 273. 
 
 B 
 
 Balance of trade, 288. 
 Balance sheet, 137. 
 Banking, 247 et seq. 
 Bargaining, 177, 446. 
 Benevolence, 27. 
 Bimetallism, 225. 
 Birth rate, 60. 
 Bland- Allison Act, 231. 
 Bonds, 144. 
 Biicher's stages, 39. 
 Budget of France, 568-570. 
 Business organization, 136. 
 Business taxes, 648. 
 
 Call loans, 247, 255. 
 Capital, 100, 123, 416 et seq. 
 Capitalization, 144, 146, 359, 621. 
 Central bank, 262. 
 Chance gains, 445. 
 Cities, migration to, 61. 
 
 Clark, J. B., 325 (note). 
 
 Clearing house, 244, 245. 
 
 Closed shop, 391. 
 
 Coinage, 117. 
 
 Collective bargaining, 84, 390, 402. 
 
 Common field system, 34, 43. 
 
 Comparative costs, 285, 305, 306. 
 
 Competition, 24, 49, 78, 88, 159, 203 
 
 467, 473. 5i- 
 
 Compulsory arbitration, 404. 
 Concentration of wealth, 335. 
 Constant expenditure, 175. 
 Consumer, the, 467. 
 Consumption, 106, 117, 434. 
 Contract, 21, 317, 466. 
 Cooperation, 26, 409, 545. 
 Copyright, 463. 
 Corporations, 140, 645. 
 Cost of production, 125. 
 Credit, 243, 538. 
 Crises, 267. 
 Custom, 27. 
 Customs duties, 627. 
 
 Debts, public, 582. 
 
 Decreasing expenses, 175. 
 
 Deferred payment, standard of, 871. 
 
 Demand, 160, 162. 
 
 Diminishing productivity, 319, 326. 
 
 Diminishing utility, 107. 
 
 Direct appropriation. 30. 
 
 Discount, 247. 
 
 Distribution of wealth, see Contents; 
 
 ideal, 114; and monopoly, 208. 
 Diversification of industry, 302. 
 Dividend, national, 104. 
 
 697
 
 6 9 8 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Division of labor, 18, 127-131. 
 Domain, public, 586. 
 Domestic system, 36. 
 Dumping, 303. 
 
 Economics denned, 3. 
 
 Economic classes, 19. 
 
 Economic goods, 95. 
 
 Economic laws, 7. 
 
 Economic stages, 29, 40, 56. 
 
 Economic thought, 657. 
 
 Education of farmers, 548. 
 
 Effort, 96. 
 
 Efficiency and wages, 382. 
 
 Elastic currency, 260. 
 
 Elasticity of demand, 163, 369. 
 
 Employers' associations, 85, 400. 
 
 Engel's law, 117. 
 
 England in 1760, 42. 
 
 Entrepreneur, 126, 138, 440. 
 
 Equality, 114. 
 
 Error, normal law of, 382. 
 
 Ethical level of competition, 467. 
 
 Expenditures, public, 555. 
 
 Expense, decreasing and increasing, 
 
 i7S- 
 Expense of production, 125, 173. 
 
 Factors of production, 122. 
 
 Factory system, 47. 
 
 Family budgets, 118, 119. 
 
 Farms, size of, 327, 528. 
 
 Federal control of corporations, 154, 
 
 494- 
 
 Fees, 606. 
 Fiat money, 241. 
 Forest lands, 469, 589, 
 Foreign exchange, 292. 
 Franchises, 506. 
 Freedom, 23, 317, 523. 
 Free goods, 95. 
 
 Free silver, 230. 
 Free trade, 305. 
 Fundamental institutions, 16, 460. 
 
 George, Henry, 364, 595. 
 
 Gilds, 35-36. 
 
 Gold, 234, 279, 296. 
 
 Government ownership, 480, 503, 597, 
 
 See also State activity. 
 Greenbacks, 236. 
 
 H 
 
 Handicraft stage, 35. 
 Hoe culture, 30. 
 Home market, 302, 307. 
 Home rule, municipal, 512. 
 Hours of labor, 340. 
 Hypothecation, 246. 
 
 Immaterial goods, 97. 
 
 Immigration, 62. 
 
 Income, 98, 104. 
 
 Income tax, 634. 
 
 Independent treasury, 257. 
 
 Index numbers, 272. 
 
 Individual standpoint, 98, 101. 
 
 Industrial democracy, 408. 
 
 Industrial revolution, 42, 47, 72. 
 
 Industrial stage, 39. 
 
 Infant industries, 300. 
 
 Inheritance, 21, 317, 466. 
 
 Inheritance tax, 637. 
 
 Insurance, 485. 
 
 Intensive margin, 354. 
 
 Interest, 415 et seq. 
 
 Internal revenue, 631. 
 
 International trade, 284. 
 
 Interstate Commerce Commission, 483. 
 
 Interstate commerce, taxation, 650. 
 
 Investment of capital, 422.
 
 INDEX 
 
 699 
 
 Joint expenses, 177. 
 Justice in taxation, 612. 
 
 Labor, factor in production, 122. 
 
 Labor legislation, 51. 
 
 Labor movement, 83. 
 
 Labor organizations, 53, 387. 
 
 Labor, supply of, 371. 
 
 Laissez-faire, 49, 87. 
 
 Land, 122, 349, 357. 
 
 Land nationalization, 595. 
 
 Land policy of U. S., 587. 
 
 Liberty, 55. See Freedom. 
 
 License taxes, 648. 
 
 Localization of industry, 131, 302. 
 
 Luxury, 1 13. 
 
 M 
 
 Machinery and labor, 129, 369. 
 Malthusian theory, 361, 374, 665. 
 Manorial economy, 34. 
 Manufacturers, in America, 76; size 
 
 of establishment, 79; integration, 80. 
 Marginal expense, 173; land, 353, 356; 
 
 product, 321, 331, 368. 
 Markets, 24, 48, 158, 543. 
 Mechanical inventions, 44- 
 Mercantilism, 37, 70, 287. 
 Mineral lands, 591 . 
 Money, 214 et seq. 
 Monopoly, 26, 38, 179, 187, 310, 342, 
 
 390, 50. 53- 
 
 Motives in economic activity, 93. 
 Municipalities, economic activity, 496, 
 
 57- 
 Mutual dependence, 19. 
 
 N 
 
 National banks, 251. 
 
 Nationalism, 300. 
 Navigation acts, 71. 
 Needs and distribution, 1 1 4. 
 Negro problem, 61. 
 Non-reproducible goods, 178. 
 Normal value, 170. 
 
 Occupation, 132, 379. 
 
 Organization of factors, 126, 321, 328. 
 
 Overcapitalization, 144. 
 
 Paper money, 234, 250. 
 
 Partnerships, 139. 
 
 Pastoral stage, 32. 
 
 Patents, 462. 
 
 Personal distribution of wealth, 335. 
 
 Poll tax, 649. 
 
 Population, 59, 373. See Malthusian 
 
 theory. 
 
 Price, market, 167; statistics, 240, 340. 
 Primitive man, 31. 
 Private enterprise, 16. 
 Production, 121. 
 Productivity, 114, 319, 329, 418. 
 Profits, 439 ** se Q- 
 Profit sharing, 406. 
 Progressive taxation, 616. 
 Property, 20, 317, 461- 
 Property tax, 640. 
 Protection, 86, 87, 300. 
 Prussia, incomes in, 338. 
 Public authority and value, 180. 
 Public expenditures, law of, 562. 
 Public finance, 555 et seq. 
 Public industries, 597. 
 Public ownership, 503. 
 Public revenues, 580 et seq. 
 Public utilities, in cities, see Chap. 
 
 XXIX. 
 Publicity, 153.
 
 700 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Quality of goods, 50, 87. 
 
 R 
 
 Race suicide, 60. 
 
 Railways, 80, 471 et seq. 
 
 Rent, 348 et seq. 
 
 Resources of United States, 66. 
 
 Retail price, 179. 
 
 Riches, 341. 
 
 Risk, 442. 
 
 Sacrifice, 124. 
 
 Saving, 113, 123, 420. 
 
 Sectionalism, 57. 
 
 Segregation of revenues, 651. 
 
 Seigniorage, 217. 
 
 Services, 96. 
 
 Sherman Act of 1890, 231. 
 
 Shifting of taxes, 619. 
 
 Slavery, 33, 61. 
 
 Smith, Adam, 43, 315, 380, 664. 
 
 Social dividend, 448. 
 
 Socialism, 515 et seq. 
 
 Social reform, 345, 523. 
 
 Special asesssments, 608. 
 
 Speculation, 255, 441, 546. 
 
 Standard of life, 377. 
 
 Standard of value, 221. 
 
 State activity, 16, 54, 86, 458, 597. 
 
 Stocks, forms of, 143. 
 
 Strikes, 395-397. 
 
 Subsistence theory of wages, 376. 
 
 Supply, 160, 166, 167, 17$ 
 
 Tabular standard, 274. 
 Taxation, 200, 610, 625. 
 Tenancy, 533, 540. 
 Trade marks, 463. 
 Trade restrictions, 286. 
 Trade unions, Chap. XXIII. 
 Transportation, 80, 471 et seq, 
 Trust companies, 264. 
 Trusts, 150, 211. 
 
 U 
 
 Undertaker, 126. 
 Unearned increment, 363. 
 United States Bank, 263. 
 Usury, 438. 
 Utility, 95, 107, 108. 
 Urban land, 365. 
 
 Value, 156, 170, 181 et seq., 270, 275 
 Variable expenses, 175, 176, 199. 
 Vested rights, 22. 
 Village communities, 33. 
 
 W 
 
 Wages, 240, 304, 307, 340, 367, 381, 
 
 537- 
 
 Waiting, 96, 420. 
 Wants, 107, in. 
 Wealth, 98, 99, 101, 102, 335.
 
 ON THE ECONOMICS OF CONSUMPTION, ETC. 
 
 MONEY : A Study of the Theory of the Medium of 
 
 Exchange 
 By DAVID KINLEY, PH.D., University of Illinois. 
 
 Citizen 's Library Cloth, leather back 1.25 net 
 
 FEDERAL POWER OVER CARRIERS AND 
 CORPORATIONS 
 
 By E. PARMALEE PRENTICE. Cloth 8vo 244 pages 11.50 net 
 
 RESTRICTIVE RAILWAY LEGISLATION 
 
 By HENRY S. HAINES. 
 
 Cloth I2mo 355 pages $ 1.25 net 
 
 GOVERNMENT REGULATION OF RAILWAY 
 
 RATES 
 BY HUGO R. MEYER. Cloth $ 1.50 net 
 
 RAILWAY LEGISLATION IN THE UNITED 
 STATES 
 
 By BALTHASAR H. MEYER, University of Wisconsin. 
 
 Citizen's Library Cloth, leather back 1.25 net 
 
 MONOPOLIES AND TRUSTS 
 
 By RICHARD T. ELY, University of Wisconsin 
 
 Citizen's Library Cloth, half leather 1.25 net 
 
 THE TARIFF AND THE TRUSTS 
 
 By FRANKLIN PIERCE, of the New York Bar. A clear, effective treat- 
 ment of present conditions. 
 
 Cloth I2mo 387 pages $ 1.50 net 
 
 ESSAYS IN TAXATION 
 
 By EDWIN R. A. SELIGMAN, Columbia University. 
 
 Cloth 8vo 432 pages $ 3.00 net 
 
 AN INTRODUCTION TO PUBLIC FINANCE 
 
 By CARL C. PLEHN. 
 
 Cloth i2mo 384 pages $ 1.60 net 
 
 PUBLIC FINANCE 
 
 By C. F. BASTABLE. 
 
 Cloth 8vo 780 pages $ 4.00 net
 
 STUDIES IN THE EVOLUTION OF INDUS- 
 TRIAL SOCIETY 
 
 By RICHARD T. ELY, University of Wisconsin. 
 
 A general survey of the subject is followed by the treatment of 
 specific problems which have been the outcome of industrial evolu- 
 tion. It opens to the interested student the many points at which the 
 science of economics applies in that immense field of practical affairs 
 in which ethics, economics, and sociology meet. 
 
 Citizen's Library Cloth, leather back $1.25 net 
 
 THE LABOR MOVEMENT IN AMERICA 
 
 By RICHARD T. ELY, University of Wisconsin. 
 
 Citizen's Library Cloth, leather back xvi + 399 pages $ 1.25 
 
 LABOR AND THE POPULAR WELFARE 
 
 By W. H. MALLOCK. 
 
 Cloth Crown 8vo 357 pages $1.25 
 
 ON THE ECONOMICS OF DISTRIBUTION, ETC. 
 
 THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 By THOMAS NIXON CARVER, Professor of Political Economy in Harvard 
 University. 
 
 An analytical study of the motives which govern men in business 
 and industrial life. 
 
 Cloth Crown 8vo $1.50 net 
 
 THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 
 
 By JOHN R. COMMONS. Cloth Crown 8vo $ 1.25 net 
 
 SOCIALISM 
 
 By JOHN SPARGO, Author of "The Bitter Cry of the Children." 
 
 Cloth I2mo 257 pages $1.25 net 
 
 A HISTORY OF SOCIALISM 
 
 By THOMAS KIRKUP Third Edition Revised and Enlarged. 
 
 Cloth I2mo 400 pages $2.25 net
 
 OTHER WORKS ON ECONOMICS 
 
 Economic Essays 
 
 By CHARLES FRANKLIN DUNBAR.late Professor of Political Econ- 
 omy in Harvard University. Edited by O. M. W. Sprague, Assistant Pro- 
 fessor of Economics, Harvard University, with an Introduction by F. W. 
 Taussig, Professor of Economics in Harvard University. 
 
 Cloth, 372 pages, 8vo, $2.50 net 
 
 The Economic Interpretation of History 
 
 By EDWIN R. A. SELIGMAN, McVickar Professor of Political Econ- 
 omy, Columbia University. [Published by the Columbia Univ. Press. 
 
 Second Edition revised, cloth, i2mo, $1.50 net 
 
 This suggestive little work is substantially the same as the articles which, in 
 the Political Science Quarterly, attracted widespread attention. Since the first 
 issue of this book it has been translated into Japanese, Russian, and Spanish. 
 
 Outlines of Economic Theory 
 
 By HERBERT JOSEPH DAVENPORT. With a series of suggestive 
 questions introducing each new topic, and a wide range of questions 
 following each discussion, reviewing its chief points in relation to subjects 
 of current and practical interest. 
 
 Second edition, cloth, 381 pp., 8vo, $2.00 net 
 
 ECONOMICS FOR HIGH SCHOOLS 
 
 Economics 
 
 By FRANCIS W. BLACKMAR, Ph.D., Professor of Sociology and Eco- 
 nomics, University of Kansas. 
 
 Cloth, 539 pages, $1.40 net 
 
 Elementary Principles of Economics 
 
 By RICHARD T. ELY, University of Wisconsin, and GEORGE RAY 
 WICKER, Dartmouth College. 
 
 Cloth, leather back, vii+jSS pages, i2mo, $1.00 net 
 
 The Principles of Wealth and Welfare 
 
 By CHARLES LEE RAPER, Ph.D., University of North Carolina. 
 
 Cloth, 336 pages, i2tno, $1.10 net 
 
 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY 
 
 PUBLISHERS. 64-66 FIFTH AVENUE, NEW YOEK
 
 
 DATE DUE 
 
 University of California 
 
 SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 
 
 405 Hilgard Avenue, Los Angeles, CA 90024-1388 
 
 Return this material to the library 
 
 from which it was borrowed. 
 
 RECVQ 
 
 T 1 6 1997
 
 3 1970 01770 9442