£x Lib r is 
 C. K. OGDEN 
 
 >CCC (ft- 
 
 (CC((( 
 
 - C ( HI 
 
 MM. 
 
 
 *t^ 
 
 ^' ^C'T-' 
 
 : rr 
 
 ff 
 
 . .:C 
 
 
 . ^C 
 
 
 . c 
 
 
 .((.' 
 
 r 
 
 ^<c 
 
 
 (€ 
 
 
 - li^C re -* 
 
 -^' .rev 
 
 ^;i^/ 
 
 
 cc cr c c -r^ 
 
 rrrrcc ^< 
 
 ((c ( c :S^ 
 
 
 
 ^~r r r
 
 ' " r c c 
 
 c c 
 
 CCC 
 
 frccr^ r ( 
 
 < C CLCf'c 
 
 cd Ccc'-xxOC. 
 
 Cd Cc-c ■ - a ' <( 
 Cd C^ crc<ij^C- 
 
 Cd.OV'-rr. 
 
 Cd <^r cv 
 
 CCdCc c , 
 
 adrcr ' 
 
 
 <3KfC 
 
 
 
 dc •'«'«:c^ <^ 
 dC^ rC<c.5 
 
 ^TToccrj 
 
 ^m< &: c€^ ^^ 
 
 t::^' d CCC 
 
 d<S d CX2 
 
 CSc d cc 
 
 
 c d«^; 
 
 r^d re 
 
 ^'C c® 
 
 ^:c:^c:c 
 
 C c cc< 
 
 UC'^^Q 
 
 T"^ <r<^ 
 
 ^'c -cm 
 
 re cm 
 
 'X xiSi ^ 
 
 IX cm 
 
 C CC4 
 
 Xc cce 
 
 C'<^^^ 
 
 Sc citr 
 
 <^ <CgC 4 
 
 _XC ccr( 
 
 ^<«sr€ 
 
 Ec rc^ 
 
 ^^^ 
 
 KXc c<rc 
 
 ^ cr <* 
 
 £C^ar( € 
 ST^cc dr 
 
 
 S-^*^' "^^d ( 
 
 #cc ' 
 
 c 
 
 
 — " ' ^-^ c 
 
 ^ 
 
 c 
 
 
 t cr: 
 
 
 'C<cc 
 
 rr,(r
 
 ^S^^^^C-^^ 
 
 PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS,
 
 THE 
 
 PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS; 
 
 TO WHICH IS ADDED, 
 
 A DISSERTATION 
 
 THE SILVER MINES OF LAURION. 
 
 BY 
 
 AUGUSTUS BOECKH, 
 
 PROFESSOR IN THE UNIVERSITY OF BERLIN; 
 TRANSLATED BY 
 
 GEORGE CORNEWALL LEWIS, Esq., A.M., 
 
 LATE STUDENT OF CHRIST CHURCH. 
 
 SECOND EDITION, REVISED. 
 
 ^ LONDON : 
 
 JOHN W. PARKER, WEST STRAND. 
 
 M.DCCC.XLII.
 
 LONDON : 
 HARBISON AND CO., PKINTKKS, 
 
 ST. martin's I-AXK.
 
 h:5 
 
 THE TRANSLATOR'S 
 
 PREFACE. 
 
 The work, of which a translation is now offered to the 
 English public, was published by Professor Boeckh at 
 Berlin in the year 1817. The present translation is 
 substantially a reprint of that which was published in 
 1828; but I have carefully revised the whole; and more- 
 over, the text has been throughout compared with the 
 original by Dr. Leonhard Schmitz, a philologer well 
 skilled in both languages, from whom the public may 
 shortly expect a translation of the third volume of 
 Niebuhr's Roman History. 
 
 The author appended to the original work a collection 
 of inscriptions, illustrating various departments of the 
 public economy of the Athenian state, and accompanied 
 with an ample commentary. These inscriptions have, 
 how^ever, been all included in the Corpus Liscriptionum 
 GrcBcarum, subsequently published by Professor Boeckh, 
 where he has repeated the substance of his former com- 
 mentary, with such modifications as subsequent reflection 
 or research suggested ; and has moreover, in several 
 instances, followed more accurate transcripts than those 
 to which he had access at the time of his first publica- 
 tion. I have therefore omitted these inscriptions from 
 the present translation ; and the references to these and 
 other Greek inscriptions in the notes have been altered
 
 VI 
 
 by the insertion of tlie numbers in the author's Corpus 
 Inscriptiomini. In a few instances tlie author has, in the 
 latter work, seen reason for modifying his first opinions : 
 these corrections liave been inserted in the notes at 
 their proper places. 
 
 In connexion with the subject of inscriptions, I may 
 here mention that, in the course of his work, the author, 
 in sj)eaking of the tenure of public land in Attica, has occa- 
 sion to quote a proposal or advertisement of a lease, from 
 the original document engraved on stone and still extant*. 
 The inscri[)tion is given in the Appendix from a very 
 incorrect transcript made by Chandler, several of whose 
 errors are there rectified. It has since been published 
 in a more correct form by the author in his collection of 
 inscriptions ; but as the copy which he has used is in 
 many parts very defective, there still remained some 
 difficulties which he could not overcome. As the 
 inscription is preserved in the British ]\Iuseum, I have 
 made a more accurate copy of it, and taken the liberty 
 of arranging the version in the text, partly according to 
 the latest improvements of the author himself, partly 
 according to what appeared on the inspection of the 
 stone to admit of no doubt. 
 
 The Dissertation upon the Silver JVIines of Laurion, 
 of which a translation is given in this volume, was 
 published separately by Professor Boeckh, in the 
 Memoirs of the Berlin Academy. It is frequently 
 referred to in the notes to his chief work ; and, notwith- 
 standing the abridgment given in the third bookf, may 
 be considered as an interesting, if not necessary, addition 
 to it. 
 
 Book iii. cli. 2. Compare the note, p. 4(57. t Cli. :h.
 
 Vll 
 
 In addition to his Collection of Greek Inscriptions, 
 the author has, since the appearance of the present 
 work, published two treatises closely connected with 
 some of the subjects which it comprehends. 
 
 The first of these is entitled, " Metrological Enquiries 
 concerning the Weights, Coins, and ^Measures of Anti- 
 quity*." It includes a full investigation of the subjects 
 which are more summarily discussed in the first chapters 
 of the first book of the Economy of Athens. 
 
 The second contains a series of Inscriptions, re- 
 cently copied by JNIr. Ludwig Ross, a professor at the 
 University of Athens, which relate to the maritime 
 administration of the Athenian state. The inscriptions 
 are illustrated with a detailed commentary, and some 
 elaborate dissertations are prefixed, in which the prin- 
 cipal subjects of the inscriptions are fully explained ; 
 and in particular, the additional information on the 
 trierarchy, to be derived from the new inscriptions, is 
 collected and examined, with reference to the explana- 
 tion of that branch of the Athenian administration 
 which had been given in his previous workf . 
 
 The subsequent discoveries of Attic inscriptions, and 
 the great activity of the recent German writers in the 
 field of ancient Greek literature and history, have, 
 however, served generally to confirm the results of the 
 author's work, and have only suggested the development 
 of subordinate parts, or the rectification of unimportant 
 errors. 
 
 * " Metrologisclie Untersuchungen 
 iiber Gewichte, Miinzfiisse und ]Masse 
 des Alterthums in ihrem Zusaminen- 
 hauge." Berlin, 1838; 1 vol. 8vo. 
 pp. 481 . 
 
 t See b. iv. ch. 11 — 15. The work 
 
 is entitled, " Urkunden (iber das 
 Seewesen des Attischen Staates, her- 
 gestellt und erlautert von August 
 Bockh." Berlin, 1840 ; 1 vol. 8vo. 
 pp. 579.
 
 Vlll THE TRANSLATOR S PREFACE. 
 
 Even if it were the province of a translator to pass 
 any judgment on the work which he translates, it would 
 be superfluous for nie to commend a book of which the 
 reputation is firmly established amongst the students of 
 Greek antiquity. I will only, in conclusion, express my 
 regret that no person should hitherto have attempted to 
 write a work, of similar comprehension and research, 
 upon the interesting subject of the Public Economy of 
 the Roman 8tate. 
 
 London, May^ 1842.
 
 CONTENTS. 
 
 BOOK I. 
 
 ON THE PRICES OF COMMODITIES, WAGES OF LABOUR, RENT 
 
 OF LAND AND HOUSES, AND PROFITS OF STOCK, 
 
 IN ATTICA. 
 
 I. 
 IL 
 
 III. 
 
 IV. 
 
 V. 
 
 VI. 
 
 VII. 
 
 VIII. 
 
 IX. 
 
 X. 
 
 XI. 
 
 XII. 
 
 XIII. 
 
 XIV. 
 
 XV. 
 
 XVI. 
 
 XVII. 
 
 XVIII. 
 XIX. 
 
 XX. 
 
 XXL 
 XXII. 
 
 XXIII. 
 XXIV. 
 
 Introduction ...... 
 
 Subject of the First Book stated. Gold and Silver the 
 
 Standard of Prices ..... 
 
 Gradual increase in the quantity of the Precious Metals in 
 
 Greece ....... 
 
 Of the Silver Money, and the Silver Talent in particular 
 
 Of the Gold Coins, and the Gold Talent 
 
 The Prices of Gold and other Metals compared with that 
 
 of Silver ...... 
 
 Population of Attica ..... 
 
 Agriculture, and Native Products of Attica 
 
 Foreign Trade of Attica ..... 
 
 Cheapness of Commodities in Ancient Greece 
 
 Prices of Land and Mines in Attica .... 
 
 Prices of Houses in Attica ..... 
 
 Prices of Slaves ...... 
 
 Prices of Horses, Cattle, Sheep, and other animals . 
 Prices of Corn and Bread ..... 
 
 Prices of Wine, Oil, Salt, and Wood 
 
 The Meals of the Athenians ; and the Prices of Meat, 
 
 Birds, Fish, Vegetables, Honey, and other Articles of 
 
 Food ....... 
 
 The Prices of Clothing, Shoes, and Ointment 
 
 The Prices of Household Furniture, Implements, Arms, 
 
 and Ships ...... 
 
 On the Sum necessary for the Support of a Family in 
 
 Attica, and its relation to the National Wealth 
 Wages of Labour in Attica ..... 
 Interest of Money in Attica. Money Changers and 
 Bankers. Loans on Mortgage .... 
 Loans upon Bottomry ..... 
 Rent of Land and Houses in Attica 
 Note [A] 
 
 6 
 14 
 21 
 
 27 
 30 
 40 
 46 
 60 
 62 
 64 
 67 
 73 
 77 
 98 
 
 101 
 104 
 
 106 
 
 109 
 116 
 
 123 
 132 
 140 
 144
 
 CONTENTS. 
 
 BOOK II. 
 
 ON THE FINANCIAL ADMINISTRATION AND EXPENDITURE 
 OF THE ATHENIAN STATE. 
 
 the Public Revenue and 
 On the Heads of Expen- 
 
 CHAPTKR 
 
 I. The Comparative Importance of the Financial Management 
 in Ancient and Modern States . . . . 
 
 II. Subject of the Second, Third, and Fourth Books, stated 
 III. Supreme Authorities for the Financial Administration ; 
 the People and the Senate. Subordinate Authorities . 
 IV. The Apodectae, or Receivers . . . . 
 
 V. The Treasurer of the Goddess, and of the other Gods 
 VI. The Manager of the Public Revenue, or Treasurer of the 
 Administration. Subordinate Collectors 
 VII. The Hellenotamife ; the Funds for War, and the Funds for 
 the Theorica ...... 
 
 VIII. The Clerks and Checking-Clerks. System of Public 
 Accountability and Audit .... 
 
 IX, How far a regular comparison of 
 Expenditure was instituted, 
 diture ....... 
 
 X. The Public Buildings ..... 
 
 XI. The Police. The Scythian Bowmen 
 XII. Celebration of Festivals and Sacrifices 
 
 XIII. Donations to the People ..... 
 
 XIV. Pay of the Members of the Public Assembly, and of the 
 
 Senate ...... 
 
 XV. Pay of the Courts of Justice . . . 
 
 XVJ . On certain other Persons receiving Salaries from the Public 
 
 Revenue . . 
 
 XVIT. Relief of the Destitute ..... 
 
 XVIII. Public Rewards 
 
 XIX. Arms, Ships, and Cavalry, provided by the State 
 XX. Approximate Estimate of the Ordinary Expenditure 
 the Extraordinary Expenses in general 
 XXI. Military Force of Athens .... 
 XXII. Pay and Provisioning of the Army and Navy 
 
 XXIII. Et^uipment of the Fleet. Implements for Sieges . 
 
 XXIV. Estimate of the War Expenditure of Athens 
 
 Of 
 
 147 
 152 
 
 153 
 159 
 IGO 
 
 164 
 
 176 
 
 184 
 
 199 
 201 
 206 
 209 
 216 
 
 226 
 232 
 
 237 
 242 
 246 
 249 
 
 252 
 254 
 272 
 288 
 289
 
 CONTENTS, 
 
 XI 
 
 BOOK III. 
 
 ON THE ORDINARY REVENUES OF THE ATHENIAN STATE. 
 
 CHAPTER 
 I. 
 
 II. 
 
 III. 
 
 IV. 
 
 V. 
 
 VI. 
 
 VII. 
 
 VIII. 
 
 IX. 
 
 X. 
 
 XL 
 
 XII. 
 
 XIII. 
 
 XIV. 
 XV. 
 
 XVI. 
 
 XVII. 
 
 XVIII. 
 
 XIX. 
 
 XX. 
 
 XXI. 
 
 XXII. 
 XXIII. 
 
 The diflPerent branches of the Public Revenue in Athens 
 
 and other Greek Republics .... 
 Rents accruing from Lands, Houses, and other immoveable 
 
 Property of the State and of Public Bodies 
 Revenue arising from the Mines of the State 
 The Custom Duties, and particularly the Duty of the 
 
 Fiftieth, or Two per Cent. .... 
 
 The Harbour Duties, and the Duty of a Hundredth, or One 
 
 per Cent. The Market Tolls .... 
 The Duty of a Twentieth part. Tithes; their different 
 
 sorts ....... 
 
 Taxes upon Aliens, Taxes upon Slaves, and other Personal 
 
 Taxes ...... 
 
 General Remarks upon the foregoing Taxes, particularly 
 
 upon the mode of Levying and Paying them . 
 Fees and Payments upon Legal Proceedings. Prytaneia, 
 
 Parastasis . . . 
 
 Fees upon Appeals. The Paracatabole and the Epobelia . 
 The Fines accruing to the State .... 
 
 Examples of Fines ...... 
 
 The Public Debtors. Nature of the Legal Remedies against 
 
 them ....... 
 
 The Confiscation of Property .... 
 
 The Tributes of the Allies. Origin of the Tributes, and of 
 
 the subjection of the Athenian Allies. Amount of the 
 
 Tributes before the Anarchy (b.c 404) 
 General Surve}' of the Athenian Allies before the Anarchy 
 
 (B.C. 404) ...... 
 
 The Tributes and Allies of Athens after the Anarchy 
 
 (B.C. 404) ...... 
 
 The Athenian Clemchiae, or Colonies 
 
 Total Annual Amount of the Public Revenue of Athens . 
 
 History of the Public Treasure .... 
 
 Of the Liturgies in general, and of the Ordinary Ones in 
 
 particular ...... 
 
 The Choregia, or furnishing of a Chorus 
 
 The Gymnasiarchy, or Provision of Sacred Games; the 
 
 Hestiasis, or Feasting of the Tribes 
 Note [A] , 
 
 296 
 
 302 
 
 309 
 
 313 
 
 819 
 
 325 
 
 329 
 
 334 
 
 344 
 360 
 370 
 375 
 
 385 
 
 392 
 
 896 
 402 
 
 415 
 
 424 
 433 
 441 
 
 448 
 454 
 
 461 
 
 467
 
 Xli CONTENTS. 
 
 BOOK IV. 
 
 OF TUE EXTRAORDINARY REVENUES OF THE ATHENIAN 
 
 STATE. 
 
 CHAPTER PAGE 
 
 I. Subject of the Fourth Book stated. General nature of the 
 
 Property Tax in Attica . . . .47 
 
 II. The Sources of Wealth in Attica, and the Measures adopted 
 
 by the State for increasing it . . . . 473 
 
 III. Instances of the Property of Athenian Citizens, and of 
 
 the Distribution of the National Wealth among the 
 different Classes of the People .... 476 
 
 IV. Approximate Determination of the National Wealth of 
 
 Attica 487 
 
 V. The Valuation of Property in Attica. Early Constitution, 
 
 with reference to the Financial Administration. 
 
 Valuation of Solon, and the alterations in it up to the 
 
 Archonship of Nausinicus (B.C. 378) . . .494 
 
 VI. Public Registers in Attica. Register of Lands. General 
 
 Register of Property . . . . .51 
 
 VII. The Valuation in the Archonship of Nausinicus (b.c. 378) . 515 
 VIII. What proportion of the Property and the Valuation was 
 levied as an Extraordinary Tax, in the year of Nau- 
 sinicus . . o . . . . 520 
 IX. Symmoriae of the Property Taxes after the Archonship of 
 Nausinicus. The Advance of Property Taxes, and 
 other Regulations relating to the Payment of them . 523 
 X. The Property Taxes imposed upon, and the Liturgies 
 
 performed by, the resident Aliens . . . 537 
 
 XI. General Nature of the Trierarchy .... 541 
 XII. First Form of the Trierarchy, or the Trierarchy of a single 
 Person. Second Fonn of the Trierarchy, or the Trie- 
 rarchy in part of a single Person and in part of two 
 Syntrierarchs, from Olymp. 92, 1 (b.c. 412) until 
 Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358) . . . .548 
 
 XIII. Third Fonn of the Trierarchy. Syntelise and Symmorise, 
 
 from Olymp. 105, 4 (b.c. 357) to the end of the 109th 
 Olympiad (b.c. 341) . . . . .558 
 
 XIV. The Fourth Form of the Trierarchy. Trierarchy according 
 
 to the Valuation, as prescribed by the Law of Demos- 
 thenes, after Ol^'mp. 110, 4 (b.c. 339) . . .570 
 XV. General Observations upon the Expense of a Trierarchy . 576 
 XVI. The Antidosis, or compulsory Exchange of Property . 580 
 XVII. Extraordinary means employed by the Greek States to 
 relieve pecuniary difficulties: namely, Foreign Subsi- 
 dies, Plunder, Captures, forced and voluntary Contri- 
 butions ....... 584
 
 CONTENTS. Xm 
 
 CHAPTER FAOB 
 
 XVIII. Public Loans . . . . . .687 
 
 XIX. Alterations in the Currency, as a Financial Expedient . 591 
 
 XX. Other Financial Expedients employed by the Greek States 597 
 
 XXI. Xenophon's Proposals for Promoting the Welfare of Attica 599 
 
 XXII. General View of the Financial System of Athens . . 610 
 
 A DISSERTATION ON THE SILVER MINES OF LAURION 
 IN ATTICA. 
 
 SECTION P 
 
 1. Situation of the Laurian Mines, and their relation to the 
 
 neighbouring Towns 
 
 2. Period during which the Mines were worked 
 
 3. Ores and Minerals found in the Laurian Mines 
 
 4. Mining Processes used at Laurion 
 
 5. Smelting Operations at Laurion 
 
 6. Whether Laurion coined Money 
 
 7. Mode of granting the Mines . 
 
 8. Amount of the Proceeds of the Mines accruing to the State, 
 
 and the manner in which they were disposed of . 649 
 
 9. Persons entitled to acquire Mines. Value of Single Shares 654 
 
 10. Labour of Slaves in the Mines .... 657 
 
 11. Profits derived from the Working of the Mines , . 662 
 
 12. Some Legal Regulations respecting the Mines . . 664 
 Note ....... 677 
 
 Index . . . . . . .679 
 
 615 
 
 622 
 624 
 632 
 636 
 642 
 644
 
 ADDITIONS AND CORRECTIONS. 
 
 Page 30, note 115, for end of vol. ii. read end of the volume. The same correction is to 
 be made in p. 50, note 208; p. 64, note 266; p. 68, note 298; p. 73, note 331. 
 
 Page 36, note 139. The passage referred to is in the Discourse on the History, Manners, 
 and Character of the Greeks, from the conclusion of the Peloponnesian War to the Battle of 
 Chferonea, p. vi., prefixed to Gillies' translation of Lysias and Isocrates (London, 1778, 4to.) 
 
 Page 51, note 224, /or note 456 read note 458. 
 
 Page 68, note 301, /o?- less amount read small amount. 
 
 Page 71, note 318, add Herod, vi. 79. 
 
 Ibid., note 320. Add According to ^Eschin. de Pais. Leg. p. 274, a talent was hardly 
 a ransom for a rich man. 
 
 Page 75, note 343. The Choiseul Inscription is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 147. 
 
 Page 86, note 391. The decree cited from Chishull's Ant. Asiat. is in Corp. Inscript. 
 Gr. No. 3052. 
 
 Ibid., note 393, /or note 225 read note 224. 
 
 Page 87, note 397. The inscription cited from Chandler is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 213. 
 
 Page 118, note 556. The inscription cited from Chandler is in Corp. Inscript. Gr.No.87. 
 
 Ibid., note 557, add Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 147. 
 
 Page 124, note 596. The inscription cited from Montfaucon is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. 
 No. 1845. 
 
 Page 130, note 629. The inscription cited from Muratori is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. 
 No. 354: compare below, book iv. note 222. 
 
 Page 134, note 653, for navKa read i/aCAa, and see Meineke, Fragm. Com. Gr. vol. iv. 
 p. 394, V. 20. 
 
 Page 140, note 665. The decree cited from ChishuU is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 3052. 
 
 Page 160, note 36. The inscription cited from Chandler is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 102. 
 
 Page 166, note 69. The passage of Gillies is in the Discourse above cited (addendum to 
 book i. note 139), p. Ixxx. 
 
 Page 172, note 97. The inscription cited Irom Chandler is in Corp. Inscript. No. 107. 
 
 Ibid., note 98. The two inscriptions cited are in Corp. Inscript. Gr. Nos. 87 and 106. 
 
 Page 186, note 156. See Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 191. 
 
 Page 187, note 159. The inscriptions cited from Chandler are in Corp. Inscript. Gr. 
 Nos. 190, 191, 192, 193: that cited from Spon is ibid. No. 184. 
 
 Page 197, note 200. See Corp. Inscript. Gr. vol. i. p. 176—291 
 
 Page 228, note 332. See Meineke, Fragm Com. Gr. vol. iv. p. 700. 
 
 Page 229. For the reference to Niebiolir, see Philol. Museum, vol. i. p. 259. 
 
 Page 232, note 356, /or vol. ii. p. 261 read book iv. note 113. 
 
 Page 234, note f, add Plutarch. Prov. Alex. 111. 
 
 Page 237, note 379. The inscription cited from Chishull is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 
 3052. 
 
 Page 238, note 381. The inscription cited from Chandler is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. 
 No. 107. 
 
 Page 292, note 622. The inscription cited from Chishull is in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 
 106, where the author retracts his rem^u•k as to the exetastse mentioned in the inscription, 
 and considers them as identical with the military functionaries so called. 
 
 Page 298, note 4. Compare book iv. note 413. 
 
 Page 303, note 24. Compare book i. note 456. 
 
 Page 460, note. Compare book iv. note 405. 
 
 Page 468, note 1. Concerning the fragment of Aristophanes, -see Dindorf's edition, vol. 
 ii. p. 502, ed. Oxon. 
 
 Page 492, note 102. See the Discourse cited above (addendum to book i. note 139), 
 p. xii.
 
 THE 
 
 PUBLIC ECONOMY OF ATHENS 
 
 BOOK I. 
 
 ON THE PRICES OF COMMODITIES, WAGES OF LABOUR, RENT 
 
 OF LAND AND HOUSES, AND PROFITS OF STOCK, 
 
 IN ATTICA. 
 
 Chapter I. — Introduction, 
 
 If the greatness and importance of a nation were to be esti- 
 mated only by the extent of its territory and population, the 
 Athenian state would rank far below the hordes of the Huns 
 and Mongols. But mere space and numbers are of little avail, 
 without the presence of that spirit by which alone the great 
 body of a people can be animated and combined. To the 
 operation of this cause must the superiority of the Athenians 
 be ascribed; by this power their scanty bands overthrew the 
 countless hosts of the barbarians at Marathon, at Salamis, and 
 at Platsea; and hundreds of subject states submitted to the 
 dominion of one small city, as large armies obey the commands 
 of one general. Not that Athens, while thus signalizing herself 
 in the field, was regardless of the more beneficial pursuits of 
 peace: and having conceived and executed all that was most 
 beautiful in art and profound in philosophy, she became the 
 instructress of all liberal sciences and arts; the teacher alike 
 of her own times and of posterity. The intellectual faculties, 
 however, are not of themselves sufficient : to produce external 
 action they require the aid of physical force, the direction and 
 combination of which are wholly at the disposal of money; 
 
 ^ B
 
 2 INTRODUCTION. [bK. I. 
 
 that mighty spring by which the whole machinery of human 
 energies is set in motion. For a state, and for a family, a 
 regular and settled economy are alike necessary; and as the 
 relations between the state and its members depend in great 
 measure upon the regulations of the public economy, so it 
 becomes impossible to obtain a correct insight into the life of 
 the ancients, without a knowledge of their finances ; nor of their 
 financial system, without an accurate knowledge of the organ- 
 ization of their governments. 
 
 For these reasons I have undertaken to explain, as fully as 
 my abilities and extent of knowledge will permit, the Public 
 Economy of Athens, the greatest and most noble among the 
 Grecian states. In the prosecution of these inquiries, truth 
 has been my only aim; nor shall I regret, if it be made 
 apparent from my labours, that the unbounded admiration for 
 the ancients must be limited, and that they, as well as the 
 moderns, were not free from stain in their pecuniary dealings. 
 Or are the histories of past ages to be written merely for the 
 inspiration of youth; and shall the historian of antiquity 
 conceal, that in those as well as the present days, nothing 
 among men was perfect? Let us confess rather, that of the 
 most excellent men of antiquity, many laboured under the 
 faihngs common to the human race; that in their more pas- 
 sionate natures these vices broke out so much the more power- 
 fully and rudely as their hearts were less awakened to piety by 
 the mildness and humility of a more benevolent religion ; that, 
 lastly, these faults (so long encouraged and cherished) under- 
 mined and overthrew the lordly edifice of antiquity itself. 
 
 Of the vast range of topics which here come under con- 
 sideration, few have hitherto been subjected to a comprehen- 
 sive and accurate scrutiny. General views and ingenious 
 speculations do not supply the place of sound investigation; 
 and the more scanty are our sources of information, the more 
 urgent becomes the obligation to use the materials faithfully, 
 and from them to deduce general conclusions equally removed 
 from flippant and vague superficiality on the one hand, and 
 the affectation of learning on the other, which adorns itself 
 with the specious tinsel of critical and grammatical display.
 
 CH. I.] INTRODUCTION. 3 
 
 Every other method either leaves the reader (as is the custom 
 with most writers on ancient history) to wander among innu- 
 merable and almost isolated particulars, having no essential 
 connexion with one another; or leads him into errors, which 
 captivate and bias the judgment by their apparent beauty. 
 Thus, for example, it has been attempted to account for the 
 indifference of the ancients to productive labour and their 
 inattention to matters of finance, by the dominion of religion 
 over their minds ; but (not to mention that piety accords better 
 with a well than an ill regulated economy) the supposition itself 
 is false ; for neither do we find that the ancient states attached 
 less importance to the public income and expenditure, than is 
 attributed to them at the present day ; nor that individuals had 
 a greater disregard for worldly possessions. If the system of 
 finance in the Grecian states was ill regulated, the defect must 
 be assigned to other causes, which are to be sought for in 
 their civil institutions. 
 
 With regard to the science of political economy, it was, I 
 admit, uncultivated among the ancients ; its relations were too 
 simple to]^be made the subjects of a scientific analysis ; for the 
 ancients until the time of Aristotle (and he also in some 
 degree), treated the sciences under very general heads, without 
 allotting a particular science to each separate department of 
 practical life. For this reason, Aristotle in his Politics speaks 
 both of education and finance, but only as incidental topics : 
 in the (Economics, falsely attributed to this philosopher, politi- 
 cal economy is treated of scientifically, and in the manner of 
 Aristotle, but briefly and imperfectly. Plato^s work upon the 
 Republic contains indeed nothing of a system of finance ; for 
 in such ideal states as that of Plato, a well regulated economy 
 was no more requisite than an explicit code of laws. 
 
 The ancients, moreover, laid down the limits more strictly 
 between those things which are capable of scientific investi- 
 gation, and such as do not admit of it ; but the art of finance, 
 whilst it rests only on uncertain conditions, teaching us how 
 to provide for perpetually varying wants from a perpetually 
 varying revenue, and how to assign to both their due limits 
 and proportions, in conformity with the powers and circum- 
 
 B 2
 
 4 INTRODUCTION. [bK. I. 
 
 stances of the state, seemed to the ancients not to admit of a 
 scientific examination. Rules for practice were not by any 
 means wanting, although they varied according to time and 
 place, and were brought to unequal degrees of perfection. 
 Sparta, with her simple form of government, was unfitted for 
 the adoption of a regular system of finance ; while in Athens 
 the expenditure and revenue were so considerable, that atten- 
 tion to matters of finance soon became imperatively necessary. 
 But it was not until the Persian war, that all the ramifications 
 of her financial institutions were finally developed ; and after 
 the time of Alexander, they necessarily lost their peculiar 
 character with the loss of national independence. 
 
 To the interval between these two epochs my inquiries will 
 therefore be confined : subjects both of earlier and later date, 
 as well as the constitutions of other Grecian states, I only 
 touch upon incidentally. In Athens, however, and within the 
 period just mentioned, the public economy of Greece is seen 
 upon its largest scale ; and all the democratic states of the 
 Greeks had doubtless, upon the whole, similar institutions of 
 finance, with such variations only as were necessarily induced 
 by the peculiar situation and circumstances of individual coun- 
 tries. For these reasons, therefore, we must the more regret, 
 that writings such as Aristotle's " Constitution of Athens,'^ and 
 the work of Philochorus, from which detailed explanations of 
 such peculiarities might have been looked for, have been for 
 ever lost ; and that others, as, for example, Xenophon's Essay 
 upon the Sources of Revenue {ire pi iropcov), have yielded an 
 amount of information so lamentably small.
 
 en. II.] THE STANDARD OF PRICES. 
 
 Chapter II. 
 
 Subject of the First Book stated. Gold and Silver the Standard 
 
 of Prices, 
 
 The amount of money required for the public service, and how 
 far the income received was capable of providing for it, toge- 
 ther with the amount of the revenue^ and the proportion which 
 it bore to the means of the people, cannot be ascertained 
 without knowing the prices of commodities, the customary 
 wages of labour, and the ordinary profit and interest of stock. 
 Upon the last of these subjects it is unnecessary to say much 
 after the labours of Salmasius : and every indulgence should be 
 shown to any one who attempts to give an account of the 
 prices of commodities : for their necessary mutability, and the 
 uncertainty of the few sources from which information can 
 be derived, impede the investigation at every step ; the chief 
 authorities on this subject being either the incidental state- 
 ments of comic poets, or the assertions of orators, who mould 
 every fact to suit their particular purpose. Nor have my 
 inquiries been assisted by the labours of any previous writer', 
 as Barthelemy^ has allowed himself to be deterred by the 
 apparent difficulty of the task ; although not the Roman only, 
 but even the Hebrew antiquity, has been subjected to such 
 investigations^. It will be the object therefore of the first 
 book to ascertain the rates of prices, wages, and interest. 
 
 The precious metals, silver and gold, are the standard of 
 prices ; although it is obvious that silver or gold may be said. 
 
 ^ Meursius de Fort. Att. cap. iv. 1754, 4to. KefFenbrink iibei" das Ver- 
 or Gillies' Observations upon tlie His- baltniss des Werths des Geldes zu 
 tory, ^Manners, and Character of the den Lebensmitteln seit Constantin 
 Greeks, from the conclusion of the dem Grossen bis zur Theilung des 
 Peloponnesian war until the battle of | Reichs unter Theodosius dem Gros- 
 Chjeronea, in the Introduction, and ' sen, und liber desselben Einfluss. 
 single scattered notices cannot be con- • Berlin, 1777, 8vo. Both these A^Titings 
 sidered as forming any exception. j received the prize. Micliaelis de Pre- 
 
 ^ See Anacharsis, torn. vii. p. 286, ; tiis rerum apud Hebraeos ante exilium 
 4ieme ed. I Babylonicum. Comm. Soc. Reg. Sci, 
 
 ^ Hamberger de Pretiis renmi apud | Getting, torn. ill. (1753,) p. 145. 
 veteres Romanos disputatio, Getting.
 
 GRADUAL INCREASE IN THE 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 with the same propriety, to be dearer or cheaper in comparison 
 with other commodities, as other commodities to be cheaper or 
 dearer in comparison with the precious metals. And in fact, 
 when we hear in ancient times of a smaller quantity of the 
 precious metals being given in exchange for other commodities, 
 it did not arise from the value of those commodities being less 
 than at present, but from the value of the metals being greater. 
 For the aggregate stock of all commodities requisite for the 
 purposes of life, exclusive of gold and silver, doubtless upon 
 an average maintained the same proportion to the demand as 
 in modern times, with the exception only of particular articles, 
 the use of which is not indispensably necessary for human 
 existence : while the quantity of the precious metals has in the 
 course of centuries been augmented by the continued w^orking 
 of mines, at the same time that their durability and value have 
 on most occasions preserved them from destruction. 
 
 Chapter III. 
 
 Gradual Increase in the quantity of the Precious Metals 
 in Greece. 
 
 The quantity of the precious metals in Greece, particularly 
 that portion of them which w^as in circulation as coin, although 
 at first it increased but slowly, afterwards experienced a more 
 rapid augmentation, w^hen the invasion of Xerxes had opened 
 the treasures of the East ; and prices rose in the same propor- 
 tion; so that in the time of Demosthenes the value of money 
 appears to have been five times less than in the age of Solon. 
 Both in Rome and in Greece, at an early period, the quantity 
 of metals, particularly of gold, was very inconsiderable : in the 
 time of Croesus, according to Theopompus, it was not to be 
 purchased in Greece, The Lacedeemonians, wishing to obtain 
 some gold for a sacred oflfering, tried to purchase it of Croesus, 
 manifestly because they could not procure it nearer home*. 
 
 * Concerning Rome, see Plin. Nat. 
 Hist., xxxiii. 5 sqq. C sqq. 47 sqq. 
 On the other points, see Theopomp. 
 
 ap. Athen. vi, p. 231 sq. cf. p. 230. 
 B. Herod, i. 69.
 
 CH. III.] QUANTITY OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. 7 
 
 Alcmceon the Athenian laid the foundation of the wealth of his 
 family, when Croesus permitted him to take as much gold 
 out of his treasury as he could carry at once\ Even during 
 the period from the seventieth to the eightieth Olympiad 
 (500 — 460 B. c.) gold was still a rarity. Hiero of Syracuse, 
 wishing to send a statue of Victory and a tripod of pure gold 
 to the Delphian Apollo, was unable to procure the requisite 
 quantity of that metal, until his agents came to Architeles the 
 Corinthian, who had long bought up and collected gold in 
 small portions, as the same Theopompus and Phanias of 
 Eresos relate^ In Greece proper there were not many mines 
 of the precious metals. The most remarkable among these 
 were the Athenian silver mines of Laurion, which at first were 
 very productive. Thessaly contained mines of gold, Siphnos 
 both of silver and gold, and Epirus, which bordered upon 
 Greece, possessed silver mines ; the same metal was also found 
 in Cyprus^ But the mountains of Pangsea upon the confines 
 of Thrace and Macedonia contained immense riches; from 
 them flows the Hebrus, celebrated for its golden sands^ And 
 in addition to the gold and silver mines which were in the 
 mountains themselves, the precious metals were found on both 
 sides of them, to the west as far as the Strymon and Peeonia, 
 and to the east as far as Scapte Hyle'. Even in Pseonia, it 
 was said that the husbandman turned up particles of gold in 
 ploughing'". On the eastern side were the important gold 
 mines of Scapte Hyle, and the precious metals extended across 
 the sea as far as Thasos, where very considerable and pro- 
 ductive workings had been set on foot by the Phoenicians, who 
 had also first estabhshed mining in that region upon the main- 
 land, which was afterwards taken up by the Thasians, until the 
 
 5 Herod, vi. 125. 
 
 ^ Athen. vi. ubi sup. 
 
 7 For more on tliis subject, see Rei- 
 temeier, Ueber den Bergbau der Al- 
 ien, p. 64 sqq. Concerning Laurion, 
 see book iii. c. 3. 
 
 ^ Plin. Nat. Hist, xxxiii. 21, and 
 others. 
 
 ^ Herod, vii. 112. Strab. ^d^. p. 
 228 (ed. 1587), and elsewhere. Xe- 
 noph. Hellen. v. 2, 12. Plin. Nat. 
 Hist. vii. 57. Athen. ii. p. 42. B. 
 Lucian. Icaromenip. 18, and the Scho- 
 liast. Clemens Alexand. &c. 
 
 '" Strab. ut sup.
 
 GRADUAL INCREASE IX THE 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 Athenians obtained possession of these mines' \ Upon the 
 western side in Macedonia the mines were so productive, that 
 Alexander the First, the son of Amyntas, hi the time of the 
 Persian war, received from them a talent of silver daily''; but 
 the chief places were Daton and Crenides, afterwards Philippi, 
 which, about the first year of the 105th Olympiad (360 b. c.) 
 was in the possession of the Thasians ; subsequently, however, 
 Philip of Macedon is said to have worked the mines with so 
 much success, that they yielded 1000 talents a year, although 
 previously they had not been very productive ; and it was in 
 this spot that, according to the common beUef, the gold grew 
 againl^ When therefore ancient historians affirm'* that Philip 
 had a golden chalice, which he guarded with such anxiety, that 
 he laid it under his pillow when he went to sleep ; and again, 
 that before the time of Philip a silver vessel was a rarity; it 
 does not by any means follow that the quantity of precious 
 metal extracted from the earth was inconsiderable, for exten- 
 sive mines had long been worked both in Greece and the 
 neighbouring regions, and much gold and silver had been 
 brought over from the East ; we can only infer from these 
 statements, that little gold had been wrought for private use, 
 and that luxury had not yet attained its greatest height. 
 
 Asia and Africa furnished by far the larger proportion of 
 the precious metals; some also was supplied from places which 
 remained for a time in the possession of the Greeks ; thus, for 
 instance, there were gold mines at Astyra, near Abydos, which 
 were still worked in the time of Xenophon'', but subsequently 
 became exhausted'^. Not to dwell upon Egypt and the rest of 
 Africa, or many single spots where the precious metals occurred, 
 I shall only notice some prominent points : Colchis, Lydia, and 
 Phrygia, were celebrated as countries rich in gold : from the 
 gold washings at Colchis arose the fable of the golden fleece'^; 
 
 " See book iii. c. 3. 
 
 '^ Ilerod. V. 17. 
 
 '^ Strab. ut sup. Diod. xvi. 3, 8. 
 Appian. Bell. Civ. iv. lOfi. Plin. 
 Nat. Hist, xxxvii. 15. Pseud- A list. 
 Mirab. Aus. cap. 42. 
 
 ^^ Ap. Athen. vi. ut sup. 
 ^^ Xenoph. Hellen. iv. 8, 37, 
 ^° Strab. xiii. p. 407. 
 ^7 Strab. i. p. 31 ; xi. p. 343, and 
 the Commentators. Plin. Nat. Ilist,
 
 CH. III.] QUANTITY OF THE PRECIOUS METALS, 
 
 and who has not heard of the riches of Midas, of Gyges, and of 
 Croesus; the gold mines of Tmolus and Sipylus, and the golden 
 sands of the Pactolus? Pythes, or Pythius, the Lydian, the 
 prince of Celsence near the sources of the Meeander, the richest 
 and most unfortunate man of his time, possessed, according to 
 report, from his mines and gold washings, 2000 talents of 
 silver, and 3,993,000 golden darics, which Xerxes increased to 
 4,000,000^ \ If we only take the third part of this amount as 
 the true sum, what enormous riches are these for a petty 
 prince ! Upon the whole there were immense sums of money 
 accumulated in Persia, which prove the abundance of the 
 precious metals, although not in circulation. Cyrus, according 
 to the account of Pliny'^, acquired 34,000 lbs. of gold by the 
 conquest of Asia, besides wrought gold and other vessels ; and 
 of silver, which is difficult to believe, 500,000 talents, i. e. pro- 
 bably Egyptian talents of eighty Roman pounds. Deducting 
 "whatever sums might be consumed by the satraps for their 
 personal expenses, or for those of the government of their pro- 
 vince, in the time of Darius the son of Hystaspes, there flowed 
 yearly into the royal treasury 7600 Babylonian talents of 
 silver ^% each of which, according to Herodotus^^, is equal to 70 
 Euboic minas, altogether 8866f Euboic talents. In the text of 
 Herodotus, however, the whole amount is reckoned at 9540, 
 and only one M.S. gives 8800, an error which it is now im- 
 possible to rectify. Besides this, the Indians paid an annual 
 tribute of 360 Euboic talents of fine gold, which, reckoning 
 the ratio of gold to silver as 13 to 1, amounts to 4680 talents of 
 silver; so that, according to the text of the historian, the 
 revenue of the king of Persia amounted to 14,560, or (if we 
 only reckon what is stated in Herodotus according to the pre- 
 sent reading) to 13,546 Euboic talents. From the productive 
 mines of India, and from its rivers, of which the sand contained 
 particles of gold (among which in particular the Ganges may be 
 mentioned), arose the fable of the ants which dug up gold^^ 
 
 ^^ Herod, vii. 28, and the Com- 
 mentators. 
 ^^ xxxiii. 15. 
 ■'" Herod, iii. 95. 
 
 21 Herod, iii. 89. 
 
 '^2 Herod, iii. 102 sqq. Plin. Nat. 
 Hist, xxxiii. 21, and Strabo, in the 
 loth book in several places.
 
 10 GRADUAL INCREASE IN THE [bK. I. 
 
 From these annual receipts the treasure of the king was accu- 
 mulated, and an immense mass of the precious metals was thus 
 kept out of circulation : it was obviously their principle to coin 
 only just so much gold and silver as was necessary for com- 
 merce and the expenses of the state". Even in Greece large 
 sums remained out of circulation, accumulated in the treasuries. 
 9700 talents of coined silver were kept in the AcropoUs of 
 Athens, besides the gold and silver vessels. The Delphian 
 Apollo had an immense collection of the most precious treasures. 
 Gyges sent many gold and silver offerings to Delphi ; among 
 these were six golden bowls, 30 talents in weight, which were 
 deposited there in the Corinthian treasury^*. Passing over 
 the numberless gifts of others, I shall only make mention of 
 the pious munificence of Croesus ^^; in addition to the pre- 
 sents which he made to other temples, he offered up a large 
 quantity of silver at Delphi, a bowl of this metal containing 
 6000 amphorae, four silver casks, a gold and a silver cauldron, 
 round silver paterae, a golden statue, three cubits high, 117 half 
 ingots of gold, weighing altogether, according to Herodotus, 
 232i talents, of which 4^ talents were of pure gold, and the 
 rest alloyed (Diodorus reckons inaccurately 120, each at two 
 talents); a golden lion, weighing 10 talents, from which, at the 
 burning of the temple during the reign of Pisistratus, 3^ talents 
 of pure gold were melted away; a golden bowl, 8 talents and 
 42 minas in weight; and also, according to Diodorus, 360 
 golden cups, each of 2 minas; besides many other valuable 
 gifts. The cups, the lion, and the female statue, three ells 
 in height, Diodorus reckons at 30 talents, so that 8 talents 
 remain for the weight of the latter. If the several items are 
 added together, the sacred offerings of Croesus, without counting 
 many other precious ornaments, amounted in gold alone to more 
 than 271 talents, exclusive of the gifts of which the weight is 
 not mentioned. If we add the rest of the gold, the account of 
 Diodorus, that subsequently gold coins were struck from it 
 
 ^ Strab. XV. p. 505. i To examine what Wesseling says upon 
 
 ^* Herod, i. 14. | the latter passage would lead me too 
 
 " Herod, i. 50 sqq. Diod. xvi. 56. ' far.
 
 CH. III.] QUANTITY OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. 
 
 11 
 
 equal in value to 4000 talents of silver, does not appear exagge- 
 rated. These accumulated masses of the precious metals were 
 however gradually dispersed, and chiefly by the effects of 
 war. When the king of Persia took with him into the field 
 money and valuables sufficient to load 1200 camels *% the mis- 
 fortunes of his army enriched the Greeks in a corresponding 
 proportion ; and history has recorded many instances of per- 
 sons who in this manner laid the foundation of their prosperity. 
 The great king and his satraps were soon compelled to pay 
 large sums of gold to the Grecian mercenaries, and to deal out 
 subsidies, presents, and bribes. Sparta alone received more 
 than 5000 talents from the Persians, for the purposes of war^^ 
 All the treasures that Athens had collected were dispersed into 
 many hands by the numerous buildings undertaken by Peri- 
 cles, together with the expenses of which he was author, for 
 works of statuary, for theatrical spectacles, and military expe- 
 ditions. The sacrilegious Phocians coined 10,000 talents in 
 gold and silver from the treasures of Delphi, which were all 
 dissipated by the war°°; and, lastly, Philip of Macedon carried 
 on his campaigns as much by the power of gold as of arms. 
 Thus an immense quantity of gold came into circulation 
 between the time of the Persian war and the age of Demosthe- 
 nes ; and the precious metals must necessarily have fallen in 
 value, as they did subsequently, when Constantine the Great 
 caused money to be coined from the treasures of the heathen 
 temples^®. How great however must have been the mass of 
 the precious metals which was carried into the West by Alex- 
 ander's conquest of Asia ! admitting that the accounts of his 
 historians are exaggerated, the chief point still remains unques- 
 tionable. Besides what was found in the camp and in Babylon, 
 the treasures of Susa and Persis are reckoned at 40,000, or 
 according to others, at 50,000 talents^". The treasure of Pasar- 
 gadge is stated at 6000, of Persepolis at 120,000 talents; and 
 
 ^^ Demosth. de SjTiimorj p. 185. 
 *7 Isocr. avfjL^ax. 32. 
 2« Diod. ut sup. Athen. vi. p. 231, D. 
 ^® Monitio ad Theodos. Aug. de in- 
 hibenda largitate, Thes. Ant. Rom. 
 
 vol. xi. p. 1415j according to Taylor's 
 explanation ad Marra. Sandwic. p. 38. 
 ^^ Strab. XV. p. 502. Arrian, iii. 
 3. Justin, xi. 14. Curt. v. 2. Plu- 
 tarch. Alex. 36.
 
 12 GRADUAL INCREASE IN THE [bK. I. 
 
 upon the whole, according to the account preserved in Strabo, 
 180,000 talents are said to have been collected from all parts to 
 Ecbatana^^ : 8000, which Darius had with him, were taken by 
 his murderers. The generosity and profusion of Alexander are 
 in accordance with such enormous sums. The daily meals of* 
 this sovereign cost 100 minas : he gave great rewards to his 
 soldiers, and paid their debts, amounting to 9370 talents ; he 
 offered 100 talents to Phocion, and presented 2000 to the Thes- 
 sahans ; the funeral of Hephsestion is said to have cost 12,000 
 talents, and Aristotle's researches into natural history 800^*. 
 He levied in Asia an annual revenue of 30,000 talents, and 
 only left behind him a treasure of 50,000^^ The riches of his 
 satraps were also excessive ; Harpalus is said to have amassed 
 5000 talents, although at Athens he only owned to the pos- 
 session of 950'*. Alexander's successors not only accumulated 
 enormous sums, but by means of their wars set them again in 
 circulation. The plates of gold and silver in the palace at 
 Ecbatana were mostly taken away in the time of Alexander : 
 Antigonus and Seleucus Nicator completed the robbery ; not- 
 withstanding which, Antiochus the Great was able to coin 
 nearly 4000 talents from the few ingots of gold which remained, 
 those of silver being more numerous, together with the gold 
 obtained from the chasing of the columns of a temple^\ The 
 immense taxes which were raised in the Macedonian kingdoms, 
 and the unbounded extravagance and liberality of the kings, are 
 a proof that there must have been an immense mass of money 
 in circulation at that time. The presents made by the kings of 
 this time to the Rhodians, when about the 140th Olympiad 
 (220 B.C.) their town and island were laid waste by an earth- 
 quake, are almost without example^^ One festival of the 
 Ptolemies did not cost less than 2239 talents, 50 minas^^. The 
 
 ^' Strab. ut sup. and others. 
 
 ^^ Concerning the debts of the sol- 
 diers and of Phocion, see Plut. Alex. 
 70, Phoc. 18 ; the other statements are 
 collected by Rambach on Potter, vol. 
 iii. p. 18G, 187. 
 
 ^^ Justin, xiii. 1, and the commen- 
 
 tators. 
 
 3" Died. xvii. 108. Lives of the 
 Ten Orators, p. 264, in the Tubingen 
 Plutarch. 
 
 3^ Polyb. X. 27. 
 
 •^« Polyb. V. 88, 89. 
 
 • ' A then. v. p. 203, B.
 
 CH. III.] QUANTITY OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. 13 
 
 expense which they incurred for their naval force and other 
 public objects was extraordinary. Appian^^ states upon the 
 authority of official documents, that the treasury of Ptolemy 
 Philadelphus, the second king after Alexander, amounted to 
 740,000 talents, either Egyptian talents of 80 Roman pounds, 
 or the small Ptolemaic^^ If we take the former, which were 
 about equal to the Attic, it gives, in the money of the present 
 day, the enormous sum of 180,375,000/. ; if they were the small 
 talents it amounts at least to a fourth part of this number. 
 An account of this kind appears fabulous ; but I venture not to 
 call its credibility into question. Let it be remembered, that a 
 great part of this treasure was wrought silver and gold^*'; that 
 the revenues of the Ptolemies were excessive, as the countries 
 where their dominion extended were completely drained ; the 
 taxes and tributes were collected by the rapacious farmers of 
 the revenue, with the assistance of an armed force, consisting 
 rather of organized bands of robbers than of regular soldiers. 
 The revenues of Coelesyria, Phoenicia, and Judea, together with 
 Samaria, were alone let by Ptolemy Euergetes for 8000 talents ; 
 on one occasion a Jew purchased them at twice this amount, 
 and moreover agreed to pay into the royal treasury the pro- 
 ceeds of the confiscated goods of offenders against the state, 
 which usually accrued to the farmer of the public revenue" \ 
 In short, the precious metals in the times of the Macedonian 
 kingdoms were spread in great abundance over the eastern 
 shore of the Mediterranean; and if there had not been so 
 much that was either wrought, or hoarded up in treasuries, 
 their value must have fallen far lower in comparison with other 
 commodities, than was actually the case. 
 
 The universal dominion of the Romans afterwards trans- 
 ported a part of the riches of the East to Italy, while Greece 
 became impoverished : thither also flowed the silver and the 
 gold of Western Europe. The golden stream-works and gold 
 mines of Italy were neglected on account of those of Gaul and 
 
 ^^ Hist. Rom. procem. 10. 
 ^^ Upon this point see the commen- 
 tators of PoUux, ix. 8G. 
 
 ■*" Cf. e. g. Callixen. ap. Athen. v. 
 p. 196—203. 
 
 ^' Joseph. Antiq. Jud. xii. 4, § 4, .
 
 14 
 
 QUANTITY OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. [bK. I. 
 
 Spain. The Po^ and all the Alpine torrents, carried down gold : 
 there were extensive gold mines in the territory of the Salassi, 
 an Alpine nation. Not far from Aquileia, gold, nearly in a 
 state of purity, was found at the depth of two feet, of the size 
 of a bean or a lupine, of which only the eighth part went to 
 dross, together with other impurer metal, which was how- 
 ever found only to the depth of fifteen feet; as Strabo and 
 Polybius relate. The neighbouring countries were also pos- 
 sessed of gold-washings. In the reign of Nero 50 lbs. of gold 
 were for a considerable period extracted daily from the mines 
 of Dalmatia. Gaul abounded in gold ores, of which some con- 
 tained only a thirtieth part of silver : it had also silver mines. 
 The mountains and rivers of Spain, as, for example, the Tajo, 
 contained much precious metal, and had been worked by the 
 Carthaginians before they fell into the hands of the Romans. 
 Private individuals gained in plentiful times an Euboic talent 
 of silver within three days; and the silver furnaces of New 
 Carthage, which, together with the mines, kept 40,000 men in 
 employment, produced to the Roman people 25,000 denarii 
 per diem, or, as Polybius expresses himself, 25,000 drachmas. 
 Gallcecia, Lusitania, and especially Asturia, produced in many 
 years 20,000 lbs. of gold**. The value of the precious metals 
 did not, however, fall in proportion to their increase, as large 
 quantities, wrought for works of art, were taken out of circula- 
 tion. 
 
 Chapter IV, 
 
 Of the Silver Money, and the Silver Talent in particular. 
 
 Coined metal, or money, is, as well as uncoined metal, a 
 commodity; and it is obvious that in the ancient days of 
 
 *2 Everything tliat is here said may 
 be found in Strabo, in the third, 
 fourth, and fifth books, in Pliny in the 
 thirty-third, and in Diodorus in the 
 fifth, 'particularly in chap. 27 and 36. 
 Whoever wishes to obtain more pre- 
 cise information with regard to the 
 situations of the mines in ancient 
 
 times, will find a satisfactory account 
 in Reitemeier's treatise iiber den 
 Bergbau der Alten. I have only here 
 incidentally mentioned the subject. 
 Concerning the Spanish mines, Bethe, 
 de Hispaniae antiquoe re metaUica, ad 
 locum Strabonis, lib. iii., is worth re- 
 I ferring to.
 
 CH. IV.] OF THE SILVER MONEY. 15 
 
 Greece, as well as in modern times, it would be an object of 
 trade with the money-changers. If we exclude the arbitrary 
 value which individual states are able to give to a particular 
 kind of coin for the use of their own citizens, the current value 
 of money is determined by the fineness of the standard : and 
 upon this point, in reference to the Greeks, and to Athens in 
 particular, I will only say as much as appears necessary to make 
 what follows intelligible to the reader. 
 
 In Attica, and in almost all the Grecian states, and even out 
 of Greece, the talent contained 60 minas, the mina 100 drachmas, 
 the drachma 6 oboli. At Athens the obolus was divided into 
 8 chalci, and the chalcus into 7 lepta. As far as the half 
 obolus downwards, the Athenian money was generally coined in 
 silver: the dichalcon, or quarter obolus, either in silver or 
 copper; the chalcus, and the smaller coins, only in copper. 
 Upon a single occasion, in the early times of the republic, 
 copper was coined instead of silver, probably oboli, but they 
 did not long remain in circulation". When in later writers, 
 in Lucian** for instance, we read of copper oboli, they should 
 not on any account be considered as ancient Athenian money. 
 Among the larger silver coins, the tetradrachms are the most 
 common, called also staters*'. The value of the Attic silver 
 talent has been differently determined by different writers, as 
 they set out upon the weight and fineness of different tetra- 
 drachms : for all agree that the early coins are better than the 
 more recent. According to the inquiries of Barthelemy''% 
 which seem preferable to those of Eckhel*^, the ancient tetra- 
 drachms, coined in the flourishing times of Athens, weigh 328 
 Paris grains (nearly 269 Troy grains, i. e. about 67i to a 
 drachma), if we add four grains, which they might have lost by 
 wear in the course of so many centuries. The silver is nearly 
 
 "*' See chap. 6, near the end. 
 
 ** Vol. i. p. 504, ed. Reiz. 
 
 *^ According to Heron of Alex- 
 andria, who has been already quoted 
 by others. The same is evident from 
 Hesych. in v. ykav^, cf. in v. yXavKcs 
 AavpioiTiKai. Phot, in v. (rTarfjpf and 
 
 Lex. Seg. p. 253, in v. iTrirplrais, 
 comp. Harpocrat. in the same word, 
 and lastly Lex. Seg. p. 307, in v. 
 Terpadpaxp-ov, 
 
 ^^ Anachars. torn. vii. table xiv, 
 
 ■'^ D. N. vol. i. p. xlv. sqq.
 
 16 , OF THE SILVER MONEY. [bK. I. 
 
 pure, for Athens did not, like other states, alloy it with lead or 
 copper, on ^yhich account this money >yas particularly valued, 
 and everj^'here exchanged with profit''. It appears however 
 probable, that the average was not so high as represented by 
 Barthelemy ; and that it is safer to take the Attic drachma at 
 nearly 65^ Troy grains : which, as the shiUing contains about 
 80f grains of pure silver, is nearly equal to 9^d. of English 
 coinage ; whence the mina amounts to 41. Is, Sd., and the talent 
 to 243/. Ids.^ It may be moreover observed, that as the 
 Romans reckoned in sesterces, so the Greeks generally reckoned 
 in drachmas; and where a sum is mentioned in the Attic 
 writers, without any specification of the unit, drachmas are 
 always meant ''^ 
 
 Before the time of Solon, the weight of the Attic money 
 was greater than in the standard that was afterwards used. The 
 weights commonly employed in trade were also in later times 
 heavier than those by which the money was measured. Com- 
 paring these facts together, it may be assumed with the greatest 
 probability, that Solon intended 100 drachmas to be coined out 
 of 75, but that the new money proved in fact rather too much 
 debased, so that 100 new drachmas were only equal to 72|-| of 
 the old coinage; the old weights being however retained for every- 
 thing except money ^°. In comparison with the heavy drachma 
 of -^gina [hpa^M 7ra')(^eta), the Attic is called the hght drachma 
 {BpaxM ^eTTTT?) ; the former was equal to ten Attic oboli; so 
 that the ^ginetan talent weighed rather more than 10,000 
 Attic drachmas^ ^ The Corinthian talent was equal to the 
 latter in value^^; the Corinthians however had staters or deca- 
 
 ^* Xenopli. de Vectig. 3; cf. Aris- See Taylor ad Marm. Sandwic. p. 
 toph. Ran. 730— 73C. Polyb. xxii. 29, 30. 
 15, 26. I 50 ggg j^otg (A) at the end of the 
 
 ' In adapting this computation to book. 
 English money, the translator has fol- ^^ Pollux, ix. 76, 86, and the com- 
 lowed the weight and value assigned mentators. Hesych. in v. Xenras and 
 to the Attic drachma by Mr. Hussey, nax^ia dpaxf^fj. 
 
 Essay on the Ancient Weights and ^^ Gell. Noct. Att. i. 8, whether the 
 Money, p. 48. — Traxsl. ■ words 7) rakavTov are genuine or^inter- 
 
 *^ Thus biuKocnai, xikiai, biaxi^t^ai, polated : in the latter case they are a 
 &c., in the Orators and elsewhere, learned interpretation.
 
 CH. IV.] OF THE SILVER MONEY. 17 
 
 litras of 10 ^ginetan oboli in weight"; 3600 of which were 
 consequently equal to the Corinthian talent. The computation 
 by litras was transmitted from Corinth to Syracuse : therefore 
 the Sicilian htra, which was struck in silver, was equal to an 
 -^ginetan obolus, according to the statement of Aristotle^\ 
 Probably the Sicilian nummus was the same as the litra. The 
 accounts of Aristotle^^, who only estimates the nummus at li 
 Attic oboli, and of Festus, who, according to the same pro- 
 portion, reckons 12 nummi to 3 denarii (whereas the litra 
 was equal to If Attic oboli), are perhaps inaccurate, although 
 they may come near the real value of the coin, if, as is probable, 
 the Syracusan nummi or litras, of the same weight as the 
 jEginetan oboli, were struck from less fine silver than the 
 Attic drachmas. Twenty-four nummi of this kind, com- 
 posed, according to Aristotle, the old, 12 the new Syracusan or 
 Sicilian talent, which last Festus makes equal to 3 denarii^^ 
 According to our supposition therefore, the former was equal 
 to 4, and the latter to 2 ^Eginetan drachmas, both doubtless, 
 like the decalitron, being coined in silver. Why so small a sum 
 was called a talent, I shall not attempt to decide ; remarking 
 only, that by a similar idiom a few golden drachmas were called 
 a talent^^ 
 
 The ancient writers frequently reckon in Euboic talents, 
 which appear to have come into use in the Italian colonies of 
 Magna Grsecia, chiefly on account of the spreading of the 
 Chalcideans, and which for that reason frequently occur in the 
 treaties of the Romans with other nations, as well as in 
 Herodotus, who, as is well known, composed or altered many 
 parts of his History after his migration to Thurii. 
 
 In addition to these values, it would be desirable, for the 
 
 ^2 Pollux iv. 175; ix. 81. I liast to Gregor. Naz., which Junger- 
 
 ^^ Pollux iv. 174, 175; ix. 80, 81 ; ! maun quotes in the place of Pollux. 
 
 of. Salmas. de Modo Usur. vi. p. 242. I A small talent of this kind, probably 
 Ap. PoUuc. ix. 87. only of 12 nummi, is that which occurs 
 
 55 
 
 5^ Pollux, ix. 87. Suidas, in v. 
 ToKavTov,' -where, according to the cor- 
 rect observation of Scaliger, vov^fioiv 
 should be read instead of jxvcov, as well , muzza. 
 as in the intricate passage of the Scho- | ^- See chop, v 
 
 in the account of the Gymnasia of the 
 Tauromenitani in d'O'.ville's Siculis, 
 and in Castello the Prince of Torre-
 
 OF THE SILVER MONEY 
 
 [bk, 
 
 sake of many statements of which we must avail ourselves, to 
 ascertain the amount of the Egyptian and Alexandrian talents ; 
 but we here meet with obscure and contradictory statements. 
 The chief difficulty is removed if we distinguish betw^een the 
 Egyptian and Alexandrian talents. According to Varro^% the 
 Egyptian talent was equal to 80 Roman pounds, and therefore 
 must have been absolutely or nearly identical with the Attic, 
 as the Attic mina was to the Roman pound nearly as four to 
 th^ee^^ This must have been totally different from the talent 
 mentioned by Pollux^% which is said to be equal to 1500 Attic 
 drachmas, but otherwise, like all talents, was divided similarly 
 to the Attic. This is corroborated by the statement of Hero, 
 who only assigns a fourth part of the value of the Attic talent 
 to the Ptolemaic, which appears to have been the same as the 
 
 =8 Ap. Plin. Hist. Nat. xxxiii. 15. 
 
 ^^ The Roman senate reckoned the 
 Attic talent, or 60 minas, as equal to 
 80 Roman pounds. Liv. xxxviii. 38, 
 Polyb. xxii. 20. According to the 
 testimonies of the ancients in Eckliel, 
 D. N. vol. V. part ii. p. 6, there were 
 84 denarii to the Roman pound, and 
 not till the time of Nero, 96, (see 
 Eisenschmid de Pond, et Mens., p. 
 33,) but the old denarius of Augustus 
 was to the Attic drachma as 8 to 9 ; 
 consequently 74 §, or, in round num- 
 bers, 75 drachmas were equal to a 
 Roman pound. ^Ye sometimes read 
 in ancient writers, that a Roman 
 pound was equal in weight to 84 
 drachmas, which is sufficiently ac- 
 counted for by the inexactitude of 
 almost all ancient authors, who used 
 drachmas and denarii, on account of 
 their small difference (9 and 3) as con- 
 vertible terms. According to Rome 
 de r Isle's accurate researclies, founded 
 upon the weighing of golden denarii, 
 the Roman pound weighed G048 Paris 
 gi-ains; hence the Attic mina must 
 have weighed 8064, whereas, if the te- 
 tradrachm is taken at 328 Paris grains, 
 the raina contained 8200. It must 
 
 however be remembered, that it was 
 assumed that the tetradrachm had lost 
 four gi-ains by time, which Rome de 
 risle, in computing the weight of the 
 denarius, probably did not take into 
 account; and then it will be found, 
 that the difference nearly vanishes, 
 and Rome' de T Isle's enquiries con- 
 cerning the Roman pound agree tole- 
 rably well with the proportion of the 
 latter to the Attic mina as three to 
 four. It is besides worthy of remark, 
 that Ideler's accurate determination 
 of the Roman foot tallies remarkably 
 with Rome de I'lsle's determina- 
 tion of the pound. See Memoirs of 
 the Berlin Academy of Sciences for 
 1812 and 1813. Thus perhaps the 
 supposition that the tetradrachms had 
 lost four grains of their weight might 
 be modified (see p. 15.), and on the 
 other hand, some grains might be 
 added to the Roman pound over 6048. 
 The supposition of some writers, that 
 the Romans had two different pounds, 
 is entirely unfounded, at least as far 
 as money is concerned. 
 
 ^^ ix. 96, where the commentators 
 should be consulted upon what imme- 
 diately follows.
 
 CH. IV.] OF THE SILVER MONEY. 19 
 
 small Egyptian talent: the very same authority, however, 
 reckons the Ptolemaic mina as the fifth part of the ^ginetan ; 
 which again does not agree ; not to mention, that, in the con^ 
 fusion of language which prevailed at Alexandria in later times, 
 the name of drachma was given to coins of the value of an 
 Athenian obolus. According to Festus^^, whose text is so cor- 
 rupt that no reliance can be placed upon his authority, the 
 Alexandrian talent was equal to 12,000 denarii. The safest 
 way, in my opinion, is to consider the Alexandrian talent as 
 something less than the Attic, although there were at Alex- 
 andria many other talents of less amount, which were used at 
 certain times and for certain purposes. For, according to the 
 assertion of Appian, the Euboic talent was equal to 7000 
 Alexandrian drachmas^^; but the Euboic talent, as far as I am 
 able to discover, was only somewhat greater than the Attic; 
 consequently the Alexandrian talent appears to have been to 
 the Attic, nearly as six to seven. 
 
 As to the Euboic talent, Herodotus^^ if the present 
 reading is correct, reckons that the Babylonian talent con- 
 tained 70 Euboic minas, Pollux, 7OOO Attic drachmas^^ 
 Here then the Attic and Eul)oic talents are considered as 
 equal. According to ^lian^^, on the contrary, the Baby- 
 lonian talent contained 72 Attic minas, a statement which 
 is evidently of more weight than the uncertain account of 
 Pollux ; and it thence follows that the Euboic talent was some- 
 what greater than the Attic. At the same time this statement 
 may not be mathematically accurate ; for according to it the 
 Attic talent is to the Euboic as 72^^- to 75 (70 to ']2), agree- 
 ably to Herodotus^ computation of the Babylonian talent in 
 Euboic minas. It is probable, however, that Solon, when he 
 wished so to change the Attic money that 100 drachmas should 
 be coined from the same quantity of silver as had formerly been 
 made into ^5, intended to make the Attic silver talent equal to 
 the Euboic, which had undoubtedly been for a long time in 
 
 ®^ In V. talentum, wliich passage 
 however appears very uncertain. 
 "2 Appian. Rom. Hist. v. 2. 
 
 ^^ iii. 89. 
 
 «^ Pollux ix. 86. 
 
 «^ Hist. Var. i. 22. 
 
 C 2
 
 20 
 
 OF THE SILVER MONEY. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 general circulation. According to this supposition^ the Euboic 
 talent would, before the time of Solon, have been to the Attic 
 talent in the ratio of 75 to 100. Since, however, the money of 
 Solon ]:)roved actually to be to the ancient Attic money in the 
 ratio of 72|4 to 100, strictly speaking, the new Attic silver 
 talent must have been to the Euboic as 72ff to 75, that is, 
 as 70 to 7^2^ : but as, upon an average, the new Attic was 
 reckoned to the old Attic talent as 73 to 100^% in the same 
 manner it might be assumed, that the proportion of the new 
 Attic to the Euboic was, in round numbers, as 73 to 'J5y 
 which nearly coincides with the ratio obtained from Herodotus 
 and ^EHan, of 72|^ to 75, or 70 to 72. This method of viewing 
 the subject agrees so well in all its particulars, that it relieves me 
 from the trouble of entering into a more minute investigation 
 of the confused and corrupt passage of Festus upon the Euboic 
 talent^^ On the other hand, the similarity of the Attic and 
 Euboic talents seems to be additionally confirmed by the cir- 
 cumstance, that in the negotiations between the Romans and 
 Antiochus, the calculations were at first made in Euboic, and 
 afterwards in Attic talents of 80 Roman pounds^^ : for it is 
 probable, that nearly the same standard of money was retained, 
 as the whole amount might have been diminished, and was in 
 fact diminished, by demanding a less number of talents than 
 before. 
 
 ^^ See note (A) at the end of the 
 book. 
 
 ^^ Enboicum talentum 7iummo Grcsco 
 sepfem milUum et quingentorum cistopho- 
 rorum est, nostro quattuor millia denari- 
 oricm. Both statements are absurd. 
 As to the cistophoii, they weigh on an 
 average 240 Paris grains, consequently 
 they were less than the jEginetan 
 double-drachmas, and greater than the 
 Corinthian stater. Nevertheless, it 
 seems to me probable, that tlie cisto- 
 phori were regulated according to one 
 of these two coins, a point which can- 
 not, however, be explicitly investigated 
 in this place. The weiglit of the cisto- 
 phori stated above is not then perhaps 
 
 sufficiently accurate. I may remark 
 here incidentally, that the account of 
 the Etymologist in v. EvjSo'iKuv vofiicrfia, 
 which states it to have been named 
 from a place in Argos, where Pheidon 
 first coined gold, is fabulous, for the 
 Euboic standard was too widely spread 
 to have derived its name from thence ; 
 and if Pheidon bad been the author of 
 it, the iEginetan standard could not 
 liave been different from it. That 
 Pheidon coined gold at all is also un- 
 questionably a fable. 
 
 ^^ Compare Polyb. xxi. 14. Liv. 
 xxxvii. 45, with Polyb. xxii. 2C. Liv. 
 xxxviii. 38.
 
 CH. v.] 
 
 OF THE GOLD COINS. 
 
 21 
 
 Chapter V. 
 
 Of the Gold Coins, and the Gold Talent. 
 
 The value of gold is more variable than that of silver, which 
 therefore may be considered as a standard of price for gold as 
 well as for other commodities^^ In European Greece there 
 were many gold coins in circulation, some of which belonged 
 to foreign states. Of these I will now mention the most 
 important. 
 
 Gold, and probably silver, was first coinecj in Lydia^"; 
 in which country Croesus caused the stater called by his name 
 to be coined, at a time when Greece was extremely poor 
 in gold. If Pylocrates of Samos really deceived the Spar- 
 tans vn\h false gold coins about the 60th Olympiad, (which 
 Herodotus''', indeed, considered an idle tale,) the Greeks at that 
 time could have seen but little gold ; for even the Lacedemo- 
 nians would not have been deceived by so clumsy a fraud. 
 
 Soon after that period, Darius the son of Hystaspes coined 
 darics of the finest gold^^, which passed over into the circu- 
 lation of Greece. Their weight, which Philip of Macedon, 
 Alexander, and Lysimachus retained, was equal to 2 Attic 
 drachmas, both according to the testimonies of writers who make 
 them the same as the Attic golden stater, and the ascertained 
 weight of coins now extant^' ; whence their value is fixed by 
 the grammarians at 20 silver drachmas, and 5 are reckoned 
 to a mina, and 300 to a talent'^, according to the ratio of gold 
 to silver as 10 to 1. 
 
 That the Athenian golden stater also weighed 2 drachmas, 
 and was estimated at 20 silver drachmas, is proved by 
 
 ^^ It is upon this notion that Xeno- 
 phon's encomium upon silver (de Yec- 
 tig. 4) is evidently founded. 
 
 70 Herod, i. 94. 
 
 7^ Herod, iii. 56. 
 
 7^ Herod, iv. 166. It may however 
 be observed, that there were also silver 
 darics. Plutarch. Cim. 10. 
 
 '^ Harpocr. in v. AapeiKor, and 
 thence Suidas, Schol. Aristoph. Eccle- 
 
 iaz. 598, Lex. Seg. p. 237. Comp. 
 Barthelemy Mem. de 1' Academic des 
 Inscript. vol. xlvii. p. 201, 202. Eck- 
 liel. D. N. vol. i. p. xli. 
 
 7* Harpocr. Schol. Aristoph. and 
 Lex. Seg. ut sup. Xenoph. Anab. i. 
 8, 14. Harpocration also states in this 
 passage, that the Attic chrysus was 
 equal to 20 drachmas.
 
 22 
 
 OF THE GOLD COINS. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 good authorities": according to this value, 5000 staters are, 
 in the calculation of Conon's property in Lysias, computed 
 at about 100,000 drachmas '^ But as no undoubted Attic 
 stater has been preserved to our days", Eckhel has ques- 
 tioned the fact of its ever having been coined'^; not only, 
 however, does Pollux'^ enumerate the golden stater among coins 
 upon the authority of Eupolis, but we know with certainty that 
 gold coins were issued at Athens, and more especially in the 
 Archonship of Antigenes, one year before the Frogs of Aristo- 
 phanes, (Olymp. 93, 2, b. c. 40/0 that money was coined from 
 the golden statues of Victory, which Aristophanes, as they were 
 much debased with copper, calls wretched pieces of copper^**. 
 
 The most common golden staters, besides those of Croesus, 
 Attica, and Persia, were the Phocaic and Cyzicenic, which have 
 likewise been falsely taken for imaginary coins by writers on 
 ancient money. The probable reason why none are extant, is, 
 that the Macedonian kings supplanted all the gold coins of 
 the cities by melting them down, in order that, with the 
 exception of the darics, there should be no gold coin which 
 did not bear their image^\ The Phocaic stater occurs, both 
 
 "^ Polemarch. ap. Hesycli. Poll. iv. 
 173. 
 
 "'^ Lysias pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 
 639, ed. Reiske. The property of 
 Conon amounted, according" to tliis 
 passage, to about 40 talents ; and it 
 consisted of 5000 staters, and three 
 other sums of 10,000 drachmas, 3 
 talents, and 17 talents. If the 500 
 staters are reckoned at 100,000 drach- 
 mas, the sum is equal to 38g talents, 
 which agrees perfectly with the ex- 
 pression " about 40 talents." 
 
 ''' See Barthelemy ut sup. p. 20G. 
 
 "•^ D. N. vol. i. p. xli. sqq. vol. ii. p. 
 206, 207. 
 
 7« Pollux ix. 58. [The following 
 passage of Aristophanes appears deci- 
 sive. It is from the Plutus (v. 816), 
 where Carion is describing the sudden 
 increase of wealth caused by the ar- 
 rival of the god of riches : ararripcn I 
 
 S' 01 depaTTOvres dprid^oixev -)(pvcTo1s. 
 Transl.] 
 
 ^^ Aristoph. Ran. 731, and the scho- 
 liast upon tlie authority of Philochorus 
 and Suidas in v. x^^x^ov. Suidas in v. 
 y\av^ liTTaTaL and Schol. Aristoph. 
 Eq. 1091, state, that the Attic gold 
 coins had the device of the owl. This 
 may be very true ; but the passages 
 can prove nothing, as in the same 
 writer, as well as in Hesychius in v, 
 Aavpeia, the mines of Laurion are 
 taken for gold mines, and consequently 
 the owls of Laurion for gold coins, 
 whereas they are silver coins. See 
 my Dissertation upon the Silver Mines 
 of Laurion, at the end of vol. ii. 
 
 ^' This supposition is controverted 
 by ;Mr. Hussey, Essay on the Ancient 
 Weights and Money, p. 88, note. 
 Transl.
 
 CH. V.J OF THE GOLD COINS. 23 
 
 in inscriptions and in writers^ as coined money^*; nor can it 
 be supposed, that silver pieces are meant, as the idea of a gold 
 coin is inseparably associated with the name of Phocaic stater. 
 Its weight is unknown ; it passed however as the least valuable 
 gold coin°^ Also, that the Cyzicenic staters were coined 
 money, is proved from many passages of ancient writers. In 
 the oration of Demosthenes against Lacritus, 100 Cyzi- 
 cenic staters are expressly mentioned as coined money^^. 
 Lysias reckons among his ready money 400 Cyzicenic staters, 
 with 100 darics and 3 talents of silver; and, according to 
 another passage in the same orator, 30 Cyzicenic staters were 
 actually paid down^\ The troops in the Pontus, according to 
 the account given in the Anabasis of Xenophon, were sometimes 
 paid in Cyzicenic staters, and at other times in darics ; these 
 staters are also mentioned as coins in several inscriptions. 
 Hesychius, Suidas, and Photius, also describe the impression 
 of the Cyzicenic stater, which upon one side was a female 
 figure of the mother of the gods, who was worshipped at 
 Sipylus, and upon the reverse, the forepart of a lion ; and can 
 it be supposed, that by this any other Cyzicenic stater than 
 the common gold one is meant? Lastly, Demosthenes^^ re- 
 marks, that 120 Cyzicenic staters passed in the Bosporus for 
 3360 Attic drachmas, one for 28 ; probably not because their 
 weight was greater than 2 drachmas, but because the value 
 of gold was then higher in that country, being to silver in the 
 
 ^* ^Tarrjp ^coKaevs Deraosth. cont. 
 Bceot. de dote, p. 1019, 15. ^coKatrrjs 
 Tliucyd. iv. 52. Two Phocaic staters 
 as a sacred Oflfering in In script. 150 
 (t. i. p. 231, ed. Boeckli.) placed to- 
 
 are meant.) Concerning the Phocaic 
 stater as a coin, see also Pollux ix. 93. 
 ^* P. 935, 13. oTi eKarbv (TTaTrjpes 
 Kv^iKT]vo\ TrepiyevoLVTO, Koi tovto to 
 Xpvaiov debaveLKcos e'lrj, Sec. Xpvcriov 
 
 gether with other Phocaic coins, can ! and dpyvplov in the ancient writers 
 no more be unstamped or imaginaiy i always mean small, that is, coined or 
 
 coins, than the /Eginetan staters in the 
 same inscription, the false staters in 
 Inscript. 151 (ibid.), and the tetra- 
 drachm in Inscript. 139. 
 
 ^^ Hesych. in v. ^cokols, calls this 
 
 wrought, gold or silver, 
 
 «5 C. Eratosth. p. 391, c. Diogit. p. 
 894 sqq. cf. p. 903. 
 
 8« C. Phorm. p. 914, 11, 6 8e Kv^i- 
 KTjvo; edvvaro eKel e'lKocrt koi oktco 
 
 TO KOKKXTov ;(pucrioi/, whether staters | Spaxpas^ATTiKas : and 13, tSov pev yap 
 or parts of staters (perhaps e/crat i eKorov kol cIkooi aTaTrjpcov yiyvovTai. 
 <b(0Kat8€s, as in Inscript. 150 (ut sup.) , rpis x'^^"' TpiuKoaiaL i^rjKopTa.
 
 24 OF THE GOLD COINS. [bK. I. 
 
 ratio of 14 to 1. Each gold stater probably weighed about 2 
 drachmas. Lysimachus and others, however, coined double 
 and quadruple staters^'; and there were also half pieces of the 
 same coin [rj^ly^pvo-oiY^, 
 
 Scahger^^ considers the Damaretion to have been a half 
 stater, which Damarete, the wife of Gelon and the daughter 
 of Theron, according to Diodorus, caused to be coined about 
 the 75th Olympiad from the crown of a hundred talents, 
 that the Carthaginians presented to her at the conclusion 
 of peace, or, according to Pollux, from the ornaments 
 of the women, which they had surrendered to defray the 
 expenses of the war with the Carthaginians^". Other writers 
 have expressed their astonishment at this supposition; but 
 Scaliger's remark is perfectly accurate ; for the Damaretion was 
 equal in value to 10 Attic drachmas, and was thus only half 
 the common stater. The Sicilians called this gold coin Pente- 
 contalitron, from its weight"', as Diodorus asserts. Since how- 
 ever 50 Sicilian litras were equal to 13 drachmas 5^ oboli of 
 the Attic standard, it is evident that the weight in gold of the 
 Damaretion cannot be meant (which could only be a drachma), 
 but the weight of silver which in Sicily was equal in value to 
 the Damaretion. The Damaretion being equal to 10 Attic 
 drachmas according to the decuple proportion of gold to silver, 
 the Sicilians, among whom gold was probably higher, made it 
 equal to 50 silver litras, at the ratio of 13f to 1. Golden 
 ^ginetan staters likewise occur^% but nothing is known of 
 their weight. 
 
 The meaning of the terms talent and mina, when applied 
 to gold, has been frequently a subject of enquiry. According 
 to Pollux^% the gold stater was equal in value to a mina ; a 
 statement which seems wholly inexplicable, unless, with Ram- 
 
 s' Eckhel D. N. vol. i. p. 50. 
 
 88 Pollux vi. 161 ; ix. 59. 
 
 89 De re numm. p. 13, 17- 
 
 ^ 4.3. [Mr. Hussey, Essay on the 
 Ancient AVeiglits and Money, p. 96, 
 has shown that tl^e inscription referred 
 
 9" Diod. xi. 26 ; Pollux ix. 85 j to, if properly read, contains no men- 
 
 Schol. Pind. OljTnp. ii. 29. 
 9' 'Atto tov aradfiov. 
 
 tion of golden staters of ^ginA.- 
 Transl.] 
 
 ^^ See Boeckh, Corp. Inscript. 150, ^•^ ix. 57.
 
 CH. v.] OF THE GOLD COINS. 25 
 
 baches we understand gold coins of 8 or 10 drachmas in 
 weighty which would certainly agree with the value of a silver 
 mina. But Pollux is speaking with particular reference to 
 the common gold stater of 2 drachmas in weight ; unless then 
 he confuses the entire question^ according to some method or 
 other of computing, a weight of 2 drachmas of gold must 
 have been called a mina. That, however, in speaking of gold, 
 an entirely different language must have existed, is probable 
 from the circumstance that the same grammarian in two other 
 places^ ^ calls 3 Attic gold staters, or a chrysus, a talent of 
 gold. The reason which prevents me from receiving the 
 emendation proposed by Salmasius®^ is, that Pollux repeats 
 the same statement twice. I am therefore inclined to follow 
 the opinion of J. F. Gronovius^', that a weight of 6 drachmas 
 of gold was called a talent, according to an idiom customary 
 upon certain occasions, perhaps, as it has been conjectured, 
 because this was the value of a talent of copper, the ratio of 
 gold to copper being as 1000 to 1. This small gold talent 
 could only have contained 3 minas, each 2 drachmas in 
 weight. This supposition is completely established by the fact 
 of the talent of Thyateira being equal to 3 gold staters^^; 
 and Eustathius even calls 2 chrysus, and Hero of Alexandria 
 1 chrysus, a talent. Probably the goldsmiths reckoned by 
 these small talents ; and when we read of golden crowns of 
 many talents in weight, this smaller kind is doubtless intended. 
 Who can believe that the Carthaginians presented to Damarete 
 a crown of 100 talents of gold^% if a talent of gold were the 
 usual weight of the silver talent, or even only a portion of 
 gold equal in weight to the value of a silver talent ? Are we 
 to suppose, that the inhabitants of the Chersonese would have 
 given a crown of 60 talents to the senate and people of the 
 
 ^^ On Potter, vol. iii. p. 169. 
 
 »5 iv. 173; ix. 53,54. 
 
 ^^ Instead of rpels xP^^^^oOs (r') he 
 writes TpiaKoaiovi or T', as 300 chry- 
 sus, according to the decuple propor- 
 tion of gold to silver. If the text is to ; ^^ Lex. Seg. p. 306. 
 bealtered,rpt(j;(tX('ovf might be written I ^^ Diod. xi. 26. 
 
 for rpels, from which the compendium 
 of the former word is not very dif- 
 ferent ; 3000 gold staters ai'e equal in 
 weight to a talent. 
 ^7 De Pec. Yet. iii. 7.
 
 26 
 
 OF THE GOLD COINS. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 Athenians' °% if the silver and gold talents were of the same 
 weight ? And even if we suppose that 100 talents of gold 
 were equal to 600 gold drachmas, and 60 talents of gold to 360 
 drachmas, these crowns still remain of considerable weight. 
 Excepting the crown of Jupiter at Tarracona, 15 lbs. in weight, 
 and that which the Carthaginians sent to the Capitoline 
 Jupiter in the year of the city 412, of 25 lbs. of gold (1875 
 Attic drachmas), and the immense one in the time of Ptolemy 
 Philadelphus, of 10,000 gold staters (which, at a festival in the 
 time of that king, was laid upon the throne of Ptolemy Soter), 
 together with another, 80 cubits in length, of gold and precious 
 stones, I find no example of such large crowns as those two 
 were, even if they only weighed 600 and 360 drachmas. In 
 the Acropolis of Athens there were golden crowns of 172- 18|, 
 of 20, and 25 drachmas or rather more ; also another of 26^ ; 
 four of which the joint weight was 135 J drachmas; one of 29, 
 others of 33, 59, and 85 drachmas. A crown, which the 
 celebrated Lysander sent as a sacred offering to the Parthenon 
 of Athens, weighed 66 drachmas 5 oboli. Two crowns, hono- 
 rary gifts to Minerva of the Acropolis, weighed, the one 245 
 drachmas 1^ oboli, the other 272 drachmas 3i oboli. Another 
 for the same goddess weighed 232 drachmas 5 oboli. A crown, 
 dedicated to the Delphian Apollo at the great festival which 
 was celebrated every fourth year, cost only 1500 drachmas of 
 silver; and consequently, if the workmanship is estimated 
 at the lowest possible rate, can hardly have weighed a hun- 
 dred drachmas of gold^''^ According to these facts then, 
 the talents in which the weight of the Carthaginian and 
 Chersonetan crowns is stated, must have been small talents 
 of 6 drachmas of gold. Yet there can be no question but 
 that as much gold as was equal to the value of a silver talent, 
 is often called a talent of gold ; as also that a quantity of gold 
 
 1"" Demosth. de Corona, p. 20C, 25. 
 Concerning the crown at Tarracona, 
 see Suetonius in the Life of Galba, 
 cap. 12, the gifts of the Carthaginians 
 to the CapitoHne Jupiter, Liv. vii. 38. 
 ConceiTiing the crown of Ptolemy, see 
 
 Athen. v. p. 202, b. d. 
 
 ^"' Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. 150, 
 ^ 13,141; ^S 11, and 139, 1, 20; 141, 
 ^S 15, 20 ; 150, § 16 ; 141, ^ 10 ; 139, 
 1, 21, 22 ; 150, § 14, 15, 12 ; also 150, 
 ^ 40, 10 ; 151, 1, 28, 29 ; and 145.
 
 CH. VI.] PRICES OF GOLD AND OTHER METALS. 
 
 27 
 
 weighing 6000 drachmas was known by the same name ; which 
 therefore in this case is manifestly dependent upon its relation 
 to the value of silver' *'^ 
 
 Chapter VI. 
 
 The Prices of Gold and other Metals compared ivith that of 
 
 Silver. 
 
 The usual price of gold can be as well determined from the 
 data already cited^ as from other authorities. The most 
 frequent proportion in ancient times appears to have been that 
 of 10 to 1, as follows from what has been said concerning 
 the stater which weighed 2 drachmas ; and although the low- 
 ness of this ratio does at first sight appear surprising, when 
 we consider the scarcity of gold in early times, it must be 
 remembered that the quantity of silver in circulation was 
 likewise very inconsiderable' °\ The price of gold however 
 gradually rose, partly on account of the proportionally greater 
 increase of silver, until it arrived at ratios similar to those 
 of modern Europe (from 13i to 1 to 15 to 1), although these 
 experienced occasional variations. When we find so late as 
 in Menander^"'', a talent of gold reckoned only equal to 10 
 talents of silver, the price of gold at Athens must either have 
 been depressed at that time by Alexander's campaigns in Asia, 
 which opened the treasures of Persia to the Greeks, or Me- 
 nander foUows the original proportion, which was still remem- 
 bered after it had ceased to be actually in force, as it afforded a 
 particularly easy calculation. In the dialogue upon the desire 
 
 '°2 Herod, iii. 95 ; Menand. ap. Poll, 
 vi. 76 ; Polyb. xxii. 15 ; the latter 
 concerning the mina. The confused 
 passage of Suidas in v. o/3oX6y, and of 
 Photiiis, quoted there by Ktister, can- 
 not be taken into consideration in 
 reference to the value of the gold 
 talent. 
 
 ^•^^ Compare also, on the subject of 
 this proportion, J. F. Gronovius de 
 Pec. Vet. ii. 8 ; the same proportion is 
 
 given by Hesychius in v. Bpaxfirj 
 Xpvalov, according to the coiTCct emen- 
 dation proposed in the notes, and 
 Suidas in v. dpaxprj. In some regions 
 of the East, gold was certainly cheaper : 
 thus Strabo, in the 16th book, speaks 
 of a country near the Sabaei, where 
 gold had only twice the value of silver, 
 and three times the value of brass. 
 i«^ Ap. PoU. vi. 76.
 
 28 
 
 PRICES OF GOLD AND OTHER METALS. 
 
 [bk, 
 
 of gain'"^ which formerly^ under the name of Hipparchus, 
 passed for the production of Plato, and which certainly belongs 
 to the age of Socrates and Plato, the value of gold is stated 
 at twelve times that of silver; Herodotus, however, reckons 
 the proportion as 13 to V°^ ; according to the former the 
 chrysus was equal to 24, according to the latter to 26, drachmas 
 of silver. To conclude from the value of the Damaretion, 
 the proportion of gold to silver in Sicily had, in the time of 
 Gelo, risen to 13f, although Diodorus, following the ancient 
 custom, estimates the silver value of the Damaretion at the 
 ratio of 10 to 1. There cannot therefore be much risk of 
 error in assuming that the Cyzicenic stater only weighed 2 
 drachmas of gold, but that at a certain period during the life of 
 Demosthenes, it passed in the Bosporus for 28 drachmas of 
 silver, the value of gold in comparison with silver having risen 
 to 14. The price of gold at Rome was still more variable. At 
 the payment of the -^tolians in the year of the city 564 
 (190 B.C.), when they were allowed, if they wished it, to pay a 
 third part in gold, the proportion between the two metals was 
 prescribed to them (manifestly to their great disadvantage) at 10 
 to l"'^ In the year of Rome 547 (207 B.C.), the ratio of gold 
 to silver was as 17t to 1, afterwards as 13f to 1. In the time of 
 Ceesar, on account of the great influx of gold out of Gaul, it 
 fell as low as 8^; as at a former period, according to the 
 account of Polybius, its price had fallen for a time in Italy a 
 third part, in consequence of the rapid increase in the quantity 
 of gold from the mines of Aquileia'''^ We also find the ratio 
 of 11^^ to 1 ; and in the 422nd year of the Christian era, the 
 ratio of gold to silver had risen to 18'*'^ 
 
 The rise in the price of gold in Greece may have been 
 owing to several other causes besides the increase in the quan- 
 tity of silver in circulation. The increasing consumption of 
 gold for ornaments, utensils, and works of art, especially for 
 
 '"^ p. 40 of my edition. 
 
 '"^ iii. 95. 
 
 '"^ Polyb. xxii. 15; Liv. xxxviii. 
 
 11. 
 
 ""° Suetou. Cass. 54 ; Polyb. xxxiv. 
 10. 
 
 '"^ Upon the price of gold at Rome, 
 see Ilamberger de preiih rerum, p. 7 
 sqq.
 
 CH. VI.] PRICES OF GOLD AND OTHER METALS. 29 
 
 sacred offerings, ^yould have contributed to produce that effect. 
 Tlie greater activity of commerce must also have forced up 
 the price of gold ; for, from the want of bills of exchange, much 
 money was necessarily carried from one place to another, for 
 which purpose gold was the most convenient. The pay of the 
 troops was given out in gold. The military chests therefore 
 required a considerable store, and the demand for gold must 
 have been very considerable during the continual wars. Pro- 
 bably much coined gold passed out of circulation by being 
 accumulated in public and private treasuries, Sparta, during 
 a period of several generations, swallowed up large quantities 
 of the precious metals, as in ^Esop^s fable the footsteps of the 
 animals which went in were to be seen, but never of those 
 which came ouf ". The principal cause of this stagnation 
 probably was, that the state kept the gold and silver in store, 
 and only re-issued them for war and foreign enterprises'^'; 
 although there were instances of private individuals, who 
 amassed treasure contrary to the law. Lysander sent home 
 1000, or, according to Diodorus, 1500 talents, 470 at one 
 time'"*. Must we not then suppose that the Spartans stored 
 up large quantities of gold, especially as it was generally used 
 for the payment of the soldiers"^? 
 
 Besides the pure silver and gold, many Grecian States had 
 a coinage, which in other countries was either wholly or nearly 
 devoid of value, and was only destined for the internal circula- 
 tion (vofjLcafjba eTTL'Xj^pLov), Of this description were all copper 
 and iron coins, the current value of which was mostly raised 
 
 ^'^ Plat. Alcib. ii. p. 122 ad fin. \ Lad the Attic device. Ou the other 
 
 '" See book iv. c. 19. | hand, Corsini Fast. Att. vol. ii. p. 235 
 
 11-2 
 
 Plutarch in Nic. 28 ; Lysand. may be consulted : only Plutaich's 
 
 16 — 18 ; Diod. xiii. IOC, who however 
 probably exaggerates, if we are to sup- 
 pose that this whole sura was sent at 
 
 words are not to be altered, but his 
 statement is either false, or the money 
 which Lysander brought home had 
 
 once to Sparta after the conquest of j not been raised from Athens, but 
 Sestos. For the latter fact of the 470 from other states, where Athenian 
 talents, see Xenoph. Ilellen. iii. 2, 6. coins were in circulation. Upon the 
 "^ According to Plutarch, most of I whole, most of the silver wliich was m 
 what Lysander sent was stamped with | circulation had been probably issued 
 the device of an owl; he then adds as j from the Athenian miut ; and this 
 a conjectural reason, that most money perhaps is what Plutarch means to say.
 
 so PRICES OF GOLD AND OTHER METALS. [bK. I. 
 
 by public ordinance far above its proper amount. In Athens, 
 with the exception of the smallest coins, no money of this 
 description was ever used, excepting that in the Archonship of 
 Callias (Olymp. 93. 3. 406 B.C.) a copper coinage was issued, 
 which was afterwards recalled^ ^'', and some other instances 
 occurred in the times of the Roman emperors. 
 
 Concerning the prices of copper, tin, and iron, in Greece, I 
 have been unable to find any definite statement. With regard 
 to lead, the author of the second book of the CEconomics ascribed 
 to Aristotle, relates that it was generally sold for 2 drachmas, 
 but that Pythocles counselled the State to obtain the monopoly 
 of this native product of the mines of Laurion, and to sell it for 
 6 drachmas. The weight is not mentioned, but the commercial 
 talent (jaXavrov i^rropiKoy) is doubtless intended. If we as- 
 sume that the commercial talent is the talent that was in use 
 before the time of Solon, it is equal in weight to 8280 drachmas 
 of the silver standard, about 93 lbs. troy ; which therefore com- 
 monly sold for nearly Is. 8d., and after the proposal of 
 Pythocles, if it was followed, for about 4^. lO^d. In Rome a 
 hundred lbs. of common lead, which were only equal to 7^00 
 drachmas, sold for 7 denarii''^; consequently the price was 
 higher than the rate demanded by the Athenian State. 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 Population of Attica, 
 
 Next to the quantity of money in circulation, prices depend 
 upon the demand in comparison with the supply ; and as the 
 demand is connected wath the number of the people, it will be 
 necessary to treat of the population. The area of Attica is not 
 easily determined, for only the coasts have been laid down, and 
 not even these with perfect accuracy. According to the map 
 of Barbie du Bocage, which is attached to the Travels of 
 
 ^'* See book iv. ch. 19. I of this assertion is given in my Disser- 
 
 "* Plin. Nat. Hist, xxxiv. 48. I , tation upon these mines at the end of 
 
 have said that the lead of Attica came ; vol. ii. 
 
 from the mines of Laurion ; the proof \
 
 CH. VII.] POPULATION OF ATTICA. 31 
 
 Anacharsis'^% Attica contains 3644^, Salamis l^^, Helena -^ 
 German geographical square miles, i. e. respectively 5'J9^, 21-^, 
 and 5, together nearly 606, English geographical square miles. 
 According to the map since published by the same person, in 
 1811'^^, which is hitherto the most accurate, Attica contains 
 39^^, Salamis If, and Helena -^ square miles, or in English 
 miles 625, 26, and 5, amounting altogether to 656. If then we 
 take the EngUsh geographical mile to the statute mile as 4 to 
 3, the area of Attica and the two islands would upon this com- 
 putation be about 874 square miles*. 
 
 To ascertain how this small space was peopled, has engaged 
 the attention of many writers. The ancients not only assert in 
 general terms that Athens was the most populous of all the 
 Grecian cities^ '°, but they also have given definite accounts 
 which establish the same result. The credibility of these 
 statements has been indeed called into question by Montes- 
 quieu' '% Hume'^", and other English and French writers, but 
 has been not unsuccessfully defended by others. Of the latter 
 I will mention only Ste. Croix, who, with the assistance of his 
 predecessors, has treated last and the most at large of this im- 
 portant subject'^', and has also taken into consideration the cir- 
 cumstances which at certain periods produced an increase or 
 diminution in the population ; to these, however, in the follow- 
 ing inquiry I shall pay no attention, partly on account of the 
 want of adequate authorities, partly because the object of this 
 work does not admit of my inquiries going so far into details ; 
 nor will I animadvert upon the unimportant errors of this 
 learned writer, which have no influence upon the main point. 
 
 '^^ L' Altique, la Megaride, et partie 
 de I'Isle d'Eubee, 1785. 
 
 ^''^ Carte generale de la Grece et 
 d'une grande partie de ses colonies 
 tant en Europe qu'en Asie, pour le 
 voyage du jeune Anaeharse, par J. D. 
 Barbie du Bocage, commencee en 
 1798, termine'e en 1809. Paris, 1811. 
 The calculation of the area after this 
 map has been made for me with great 
 accuracy by Mr. Kloeden, who is well 
 known as skilled in this point. 
 
 * See Mr. Clinton's computation 
 of the Area of Attica, founded on dif- 
 ferent data, in his Fast. Hellen. vol. ii. 
 p. 473, ed. 3.— Transl. 
 
 ^'^ Meursius de F. A. iv. p. 24. 
 See Thucyd. i. 80. 
 
 ''^ Esprit des Lois xxxiii. T. 
 
 ^'" Essay upon the Populousness of 
 Ancient Nations, p. 237 sqq. 
 
 '^^ Memoires de TAcade'mie des 
 Inscriptions, toraexlviii.
 
 32 POPULATION OF ATTICA. [bK. I. 
 
 I pass over all attempts to determine the population of Athens 
 from its military force, since the data, which in this case it 
 would be necessary to consider, are in a great measure too 
 general, without any exact distinction between the classes of the 
 citizens, slaves, and resident aliens, and also because in every 
 State the persons incapable of bearing arms form a considerable 
 number ; on which account the native military force can only 
 prove that a nation had not fewer inhabitants than this or that 
 definite number, but not accurately how great the whole amount 
 was. 
 
 Tlie whole population of Attica would be known, if we 
 could separately ascertain the number of the citizens, resident 
 aliens, and slaves, together with their wives and children. The 
 largest part of the accounts extant are of the number of the 
 citizens ; but they differ widely, according to the difference of 
 the periods, and the greater or less accuracy of the statements; 
 but that their number was considerable, may be collected from 
 Xenophon^^% w^ho states that the Athenians were equal in 
 number to all the Boeotians — that is, the citizens of the one 
 country to the citizens of the other. All particular statements, 
 with the exception of one only, w^hich belongs to the most 
 ancient times, vary between nearly twenty and thirty thousand. 
 Philochorus^^^ indeed related, that even in the reign of Cecrops, 
 20,000 men had been enumerated, by which the writer pro- 
 bably meant citizens ; this, however, is manifestly a fabulous 
 tradition, which was probably adapted to a later census of the 
 citizens. The following account of Pollux' ^^ is more worthy of 
 attention. He states that each of the 360 ancient houses which 
 were included before the time of Cleisthenes in the four 
 ancient tribes, contained 30 men, whence the houses were 
 called TpLaKdhe<^', from which it results that the number of 
 citizens was 10,800. If to this it is objected that a limited 
 number is in such a case impossible, it may be fairly answered, 
 that at some one period, when the constitution of the tribes was 
 
 '^^ 3Iem. Socrat. iii. 5, 2. one another, but nXrjdos (wliole niini- 
 
 ^^* Ap, Scliol. Pincl. Olymp, ix. G8, b;^r of the people) is a more accurate 
 
 where the words tov tcov 'Adrjvaioiv expression. 
 driixov Kal TO TrXrjdos are not opposed to '^^ viii. HI.
 
 CH. VII.] POPULATION OF ATTICA. 33 
 
 regulated, this number was taken as an average, although it did 
 not remain so. In the same manner that the Romans called 
 the captain a centurion, even if he commanded only 60 men, a 
 house might have been called a rpiaKas, although it contained 
 50 or more men. That the number of the citizens amounted to 
 30,000, was a customary assumption from the time of the 
 Persian to the end of the Peloponnesian war. Herodotus sup- 
 poses Aristagoras of Miletus to speak of 30,000 Athenians who 
 had the right of voting'*^. Aristophanes in the Ecclesiazusse'*% 
 which was written after the Anarchy, speaks even of more than 
 30,000 ; and the author of the Axiochus'*^ also states that the 
 assembly in which the generals were condemned after the 
 victory of Arginusae, was attended by a greater number than 
 that just mentioned : these accounts, however, are manifestly 
 overrated. Aristagoras, to express himself with effect, would not 
 fail to select the highest number ; nor need the words of a comic 
 poet be taken so exactly ; and the author of the Axiochus could 
 not have seen accurate accounts of the population, which, after 
 the great defeats in Sicily, and a war carried on so long with 
 alternate success, would doubtless have shown a very different 
 number. Even if we were to assume that in the above enume- 
 rations of citizens who voted in the assembly, many were com- 
 prised who had not properly any right of voting, but who 
 assumed that privilege unlawfully, still we should never arrive 
 at so high a number as 30,000, especially since all the citizens, 
 even on the most important affairs, never attended the assembly. 
 The accounts which are founded upon real enumerations are of 
 a very different character. On an occasion of a distribution of 
 com, which, like all other distributions, was made according to 
 the registers of the lexiarchs among the adult citizens of 18 
 years of age and upwards, a scrutiny was instituted in the 
 Archonship of Lysimachides (Olymp. 83, 4, 445 B.C.) into the 
 genuineness of their birth {jvtjo-lotijs). There were then 
 found, according to Philochorus, only 14,240 genuine Athe- 
 nians ; and 4760, who had assumed the rights of citizenship 
 unjustly, were in consequence sold as slaves. Previously, 
 
 '*" V. 97. '»7 Vs. 1124. 1" Cap. 12. 
 
 D
 
 34 
 
 POPULATION OF ATTICA. 
 
 Qbk. 
 
 I. 
 
 therefore, there were 19,000 persons who passed for citizens. 
 The amount is perhaps stated in too round a number to be con- 
 sidered as completely exact. Plutarch, who probably only follows 
 Philochorus, gives 14,040 as genuine, assuming that 5000 were 
 rejected'". At the breaking out of the Peloponnesian war, 
 besides 13,000 hoplitse appointed for service in the field, there 
 were also 16,000 others in Athens, who consisted of the oldest 
 and youngest citizens and a certain number of resident 
 aliens' ^°; the number of citizens must therefore at that time 
 have been higher. AVhatever vacancies were caused by war, 
 and not replaced by a fresh growth, were filled up by the occa- 
 sional creation of new citizens, as was the case for example 
 during the Archonship of Euchd (Olymp. 94, 2, 403 b.c.) Thus 
 in the first speech of Demosthenes against Aristogeiton'^', we 
 find the number of citizens reckoned as nearly 20,000. Plato, 
 in the Critias, assumes the same amount for the most ancient 
 times of Athens, in which he has, doubtless, transferred the 
 number that was commonly computed in his own time to the 
 earhest periods of the state ; and the later Grecian writers, as 
 Libanius, follow the same statement'^^ An occurrence of the 
 same period exactly coincides with the statement in the speech 
 of Demosthenes. When Lycurgus divided the property of 
 Diphilus, amounting to 160 talents, each citizen received 50 
 
 '2^ Philociiorus ap. Scliol. Aristopli. 
 Vesp.716. Plutarcli.Pericl.37. [The 
 word in Plutarch is eTrpdOrjaav, for 
 which ;Mr. Clinton (vol. ii. ad a. 
 444, and app. p. 479, ed. 3) reads 
 uTTTjXdSqa-av ; and in addition to the 
 autliorities whicli he quotes, see 
 Photius in v. e^eo-i?, Bekk. Anecd. p. 
 201, 17, and p. 439, 32. It appeai« 
 that each borough inquired into the 
 genuineness of its own members; and 
 that those who were rejected by the 
 votes of the burghers (u7ro'v//-;;^icr^eVres) 
 lost the rights of citizenship. If they 
 then appealed to the decision of a 
 court of justice, and were a second time 
 rejected, their persons were sold, and 
 their property confiscated. — Transl.] 
 
 130 Thucyd. ii. 13r 
 
 '^^ P. 7o5, 24. The spuriousness of 
 the second speech is acknowledged by 
 both ancienis and moderns. Dionysius 
 doubts whether the first was the pro- 
 duction of Demosthenes; audinllarpor 
 cration (in v. 6<;(op\s) it is quoted with a 
 suspicion of its authenticity. 1 leave 
 this point undecided, but it certainly 
 belongs to that period. For the usage 
 of ofxov in the passage referred to, see 
 Ilesych. Suid. Harpocr. and Phot, in 
 
 V. OflOV. 
 
 ^'■^'^ See Meui-sius de F. A. iv. Ac- 
 cording to the interpretation of the 
 Scholiast, the same number of citizens 
 may be inferred from Aristoph, Vesp. 
 707 ; it is not, however, distinctly ex- 
 pressed in the words of Arist(5phanes.
 
 CH. VII.] POPULATION OF ATTICA, 35 
 
 drachmas^ which gives 19,200 for their whole numbe^''^ 
 The assertion that in the reign of Antij^ater (Olymp. 114, 2, 
 323 B.C.) Athens contained 21,000 citizens''^, is inadmissible, 
 as being taken from a later enumeration ; and Diodorus'^^ even 
 goes so far as to suppose that there were 31,000, reckoning 
 22,000 instead of 12,000 as in Plutarch, who were deprived of 
 the rights of citizenship, and he assumes 9000 as the surplus, 
 agreeing in the latter point with Plutarch. These 12,000 
 rejected citizens, some of whom had left the country, were 
 restored to their rights in Olymp. 115, 3, 318 b.c.'^^ Soon 
 after this an enumeration of the people occurs, which is the 
 very one to which the number mentioned in Plutarch of the 
 citizens w^ho remained and were disfranchised in the reign of 
 Antipater, was adapted. It was carried on by Demetrius 
 Phalereus when Archon in Olymp. 117, 4, 309 B.C.'", and 
 yielded, according to Ctesicles'^% 21,000 citizens, 10,000 resi- 
 dent aliens, and 400,000 slaves. From this very important 
 statement, the whole number of the population of Attica has 
 been variously determined. According to the usual rule of 
 statistics, the adults have been generally taken as a fourth part 
 of the population. This gave for the citizens 84,000, and for 
 the aliens 40,000. But when they came to the slaves, these 
 calculators fell into an embarrassment; for, according to the 
 same, or a somewhat lower proportion, their number came out 
 far above what could be deemed probable. Hume, wishing to 
 show that the population of ancient times has been greatly over- 
 rated, contends with many reasons against this number of 
 slaves, and ends by substituting 40,000 in the place of 400,000, 
 whom he considers as the adults, to which it would be then 
 necessary to add the women and children. But his arguments 
 are partly inconclusive, and partly founded upon false suppo- 
 
 ^^^ Lives of the Ten Oi-ators near 
 the end of the Life of Lyciirgus. Tlje 
 addition, r) as rives fivav, does not de- 
 serve any attention. 
 
 ^3' Plutarch. Phoc. 28. 
 
 135 xviii. 18. It appears to me that 
 the passage ought by no means to be 
 
 altered, as Diodorus so frequently ex- 
 aggerates numbers. 
 
 ^36 Diod. xviii. 66. 
 
 ^'7 This is the right date which Ste. 
 Croix has given, p. 64. 
 
 ^^8 Ap. Athen. vi. p. 272, B. 
 
 D 2
 
 36 POPULATION OF ATTICA. [bK. I. 
 
 sitions. Thus all that he says concerning the national wealth 
 of Attica, that it was only equal to 6000 talents, is completely 
 false; and, in the next place, slaves were not computed by 
 adults or fathers of families, which is a term wholly inappHcable 
 'to slaves; but they were counted, like sheep or cattle, by the 
 head, and were regarded in the same light with property, as 
 Gillies'^® has already observed, for they were in the strictest 
 sense a personal possession : 400,000 is therefore the sum total 
 of the slaves ; and the population of Attica, deducting the non- 
 settled aliens, would amount, on this supposition, to 524,000 
 souls. Wallace's computation is higher, for he makes the 
 whole population amount to more than 580,000 ; and Sainte 
 Croix goes as far as 639,500. The latter writer erroneously 
 adds 100,000 children to the number of slaves, and likewise 4 J 
 and not 4 for every male adult or father of a family, so that 
 the free as well as the slave population is made more numerous. 
 As, however, this proportion appears to be more correct for 
 southern countries, the citizens with their families maybe fairly 
 taken at 94,500, and the resident aliens at 45,000. In order, 
 however, not to proceed solely upon the period of Demetrius, 
 but upon the mean average of 20,000 citizens, I reckon only 
 90,000 citizens, and 45,000 resident aliens. With regard to 
 the total amount of slaves, it is stated too much in round 
 numbers for perfect accuracy; the historian doubtless added 
 whatever was wanting to complete the last hundred thousand, 
 although the correct number might not have been so great by 
 several thousands. It will be sufficient to reckon 365,000 
 slaves, together with women and children, which latter, how- 
 ever, were proportionally few. Adding to these 135,000 free 
 inhabitants, we may take, as a mean average of the population, 
 500,000 in round numbers, of whom the larger proportion were 
 men, since fewer female than male slaves were kept, and not 
 many slaves were married. 
 
 The ratio of the citizens to the slaves can be consequently 
 taken as rather more than one to four ; and the ratio of the 
 
 '3^ Essays on the History, Customs, and Character of the Greeks, p. 15 of 
 the German translation of Maclier.
 
 CH. VII.] 
 
 POPULATION OF ATTICA, 
 
 37 
 
 free population to the slaves as nearly one to three. In some 
 of the American sugar islands the ratio of the slaves to the free 
 population was as great as six to one. This number of slaves 
 cannot appear too large, if the political circumstances of Attica 
 are taken into consideration. Even the poor citizens used to 
 have a slave''"' for the care of their household affairs. In every 
 moderate establishment many were employed for all sorts of 
 occupations, such as grinders, bakers, cooks, tailors, errand- 
 boys, or to accompany the master and mistress, who seldom 
 went out without an attendant. Any one who was expensive, 
 and wished to attract attention, took, perhaps, three attendants 
 with him'*^ We even hear of philosophers who kept 10 
 slaves'". Slaves were also let out as hired servants ; they per- 
 formed all the labour connected with the care of cattle and 
 agriculture ; they were employed in the working of the mines 
 and furnaces; all manual labour and the lower branches of 
 trade were in a great measure carried on by them ; large gangs 
 laboured in the numerous workshops, for which Athens was 
 celebrated ; and a considerable number were employed in the 
 merchant vessels and the fleet. Not to enumerate many in- 
 stances of persons who had a smaller number of slaves, Timar- 
 chus kept in his workshop 11 or 12^"; Demosthenes' father, 
 52 or 53, besides the female slaves in his house'** ; Lysias and 
 Polemarchus, 120'*'. Plato expressly remarks that the free 
 inhabitants had frequently 50 slaves, and the rich even more'*' ; 
 Philemonides had 300, Hipponicus 600, Nicias 1000 slaves 
 in the mines alone'*'. These facts prove the existence of an 
 immense number of slaves. 
 
 But Hume raises an objection out of Xenophon. Xenophon'*' 
 proposed to the state to buy public slaves for the mines, and par- 
 ticularly mentions how large a revenue the state would receive 
 from them, if it had 10,000 to begin with : at the same time, he 
 
 ^^ See for example the beginning of 
 the Phitus of Aristophanes. 
 
 '** Demosth. pro. Phorm. p. 958, 
 14. 
 
 '*2 Ste. Croix, p. 172. 
 
 "' iEschin. cont. Tiniarch. p. 
 
 18. 
 
 "* Demosth. cont. Aphob. A. 
 816, cf. p. 828, 1. 
 
 ^^^ Lysias cont. Eratosth. p. 395. 
 *^« De Republ. ix. p. 578, D E. 
 ^*' Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 
 '*« Ut. sup.
 
 38 
 
 POPULATION OF ATTICA. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 adds the following remark : " that the mines are able to receive 
 many times this numl^er, every body will allow, who remembers 
 how much the slave-duty pvoduced before the occurrences at 
 Decelea." From this statement, Hume infers that the number 
 cannot have been so excessive, for that the diminution by the 
 war of Decelea only amounted to 20,000'^^, and the increase 
 of 10,000 does not stand in any considerable proportion to so 
 large a number as 400,000. It must, however, be considered 
 that after the w^ar of Decelea. the Athenians probably ceased to 
 keep many slaves on account of the facility of escape, and that 
 a still greater number than ran away may have been dismissed. 
 Xenophon himself says that the number had been very great 
 formerly ; and he means that their numbers before the war of 
 Decelea prove that the mines, of which alone he is speaking, 
 could afford employment to many times 10,000. At the same 
 time, I will not deny that the passage has a very strange appear- 
 ance, and is obscured by manifold difficulties ; but this is the very 
 reason why we should avoid founding any argument upon it^. 
 
 There are two other statements, equally called into ques- 
 tion by Hume, which are far more incomprehensible, viz. : of 
 Timseus, that Corinth once had possessed 460,000, and of Aris- 
 totle, that ^gina had contained 470,000 slaves'^". Neverthe- 
 less the numbers do not appear to be corrupt. That the Corin- 
 thians kept a very large number of slaves is proved by the 
 expression Chcenix-measurers [')(OLViH:oiJbeTpai) by which they 
 were distinguished ; nor is it possible that ^Egina before and 
 during the Persian w^ar, up to the time of its decline, could have 
 been a great commercial town, and have had an extensive naval 
 force, without a large population, and above all, many slaves. 
 Its naval dominion, and its powerful resistance against Athens, 
 are incompatible wdth a small population. Why, then, may we 
 
 '^» Thucyd. vii. 27. 
 . *» An importaut statement contained 
 in a fragment of Ilyperides with re- 
 gard to the slave-population, which has 
 been overlooked by the author, is 
 quoted by Islr. Clinton from Suidas in 
 V, d7r(ylrr)(f)taaTo (F. II. vol. ii. p. 400, 
 
 ed. 3), where it is mentioned that the 
 slaves employed in the silver mines and 
 in country labour were more than 
 150,000.— Traxsl. 
 
 '5° Athen. vi. p. 272, B. D. Schol. 
 Find. Olymp. viii. 30.
 
 CH. VII.] 
 
 POPULATION OF ATTICA. 
 
 39 
 
 not suppose that 470,000 slaves^ lived in this small island, whose 
 area scarcely exceeded forty English square miles ? there still 
 remained sufficient space, as slaves never occupied much room, 
 ^gina, as well as the Peloponnese^'^ and particularly Corinth, 
 received supplies from the countries upon the Black Sea. In 
 the mean time, it is hardly necessary to remark, that this large 
 population of Corinth and ^gina must only be understood of 
 the early times, before Athens had obtained possession of the 
 commerce of Greece and the sovereignty of the sea. 
 
 In what manner this population of 500,000 souls in Attica 
 was distributed, cannot be accurately determined. Athens 
 itself contained above 10,000 houses. In general only one 
 family lived in a house, and fourteen free inhabitants were at 
 that time a large number for one house or for one family^^^. 
 Lodging houses {avvoLKiat) were however inhabited by several 
 families, and manufactories contained many hundreds of slaves. 
 The district of the mines must also have been very thickly 
 peopled. The circumference of the city, together with the sea- 
 ports, was equal to 200 stadii. The mines were in a space 60 
 stadii in width: the other dimension is not known. If 180,000 
 persons are reckoned for the city and harbours, and 20,000 for 
 the mines, and the space for both taken at 32 square miles 
 English, the number assumed would not be too high. There 
 then remain 300,000 souls for the other 608 square miles, which 
 gives something less than 493^ to a square mile, which, with 
 the number of small towns or market-places, villages, and farms, 
 that were in Attica, is not to be wondered at. Now this popu- 
 lation necessarily required a large supply of provisions. It 
 should, however, be borne in mind, that slaves were badly fed, 
 and above all, that corn alone was requisite for their suste- 
 nance. How large a quantity of com was required, and how 
 the necessary supplies could be procured, I shall endeavour to 
 determine presently. 
 
 Mr. Clinton proposes, in the pas- 
 of Athen£eus, to reduce the 
 number of slaves at Corinth to 60,000, 
 
 70,000. Fast. Hell. vol. ii. p. 515, ed. 
 3. — Transl. 
 
 ^^^ Herod, vii. 147, and thence Poly- 
 aenus in the Strategics. 
 
 '" Xenoph. :Mem. Soc. ii. 7, 2.
 
 40 
 
 AGRICULTURE, AND 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 Chapter VIII. 
 
 Agriculture, and Native Products of Attica, 
 
 All commodities which are necessary for the purposes of life 
 are procured either by the domestic production and manufac- 
 ture of the raw material, or by foreign commerce. Attica was 
 not so unsuited for agriculture as is often supposed. The soil 
 was indeed stony and uneven in many places; a great part 
 was bare rock, where nothing could be sown ; the less fertile 
 soil, however, produced barley^^^ and wheat, the latter indeed 
 with great difficulty ; and the mildness of the climate allowed 
 all the more valuable products of the earth to ripen the earliest, 
 and to go out of season the latest'^*. Every sort of plant and 
 animal throve, in spite of the poverty of the soiP". Art also 
 undoubtedly performed its share ; for the ancients in all con- 
 cerns of common Hfe were possessed of sound principles founded 
 on experience ; and at so early a period as the time of Socra- 
 tes, writings upon agriculture were in existence^^. Agricul- 
 ture was in as great estimation among the Athenians as with 
 the Romans, if we may judge from the high encomiums of 
 Xenophon and Aristotle^*^ The latter calls an agricultural 
 people the most just ; agriculture is represented as that species 
 of industry which is most just and conformable to nature : the 
 most just, because it does not gain from men, either according 
 to their wills, as in paid labour and commerce, or against their 
 wills, as in war ; the most agreeable to nature, because every- 
 thing receives nourishment from its mother, and the earth is 
 the mother of men. The ancients also esteemed agriculture, 
 because it made their bodies and minds strong and active, and 
 
 '" Thucyd. 1, 2, where the com- 
 mentators quote other passages upon 
 the sterility of the soil. See more 
 particularly the Introduction to Xeno- 
 phon's Treatise on the Revenues. 
 
 15* Xenoph. Ibid. 
 
 155 Plat. Crit. p. 110, E. 
 
 156 See my Preface to the Dialogues 
 
 of Simon the Socratic Philosopher, p. 
 xix. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. (Econ. 4 sqq. Aristot. 
 Polit. vi. 4, and the first book of the 
 CEconomics attributed to Aristotle, 
 which at least contains the principles 
 of that philosopher.
 
 CH. VIII.] NATIVE PRODUCTS OP ATTICA. 
 
 41 
 
 trained them for service in the field, whereas most kinds of 
 manufactures and commerce weakened and enervated both. 
 The opulent, however, only occupied themselves with the 
 superintendence ; and most of the manual labour fell upon the 
 slaves, who were servants, and frequently also stewards, and who 
 unquestionably lessened the expenses of cultivation, whatever 
 the moderns may advance against the cheapness of slave labour. 
 Thus the cultivator derived sufficient support from his own farm, 
 and in dear times the agriculturists even grew unduly rich"°. 
 
 The most considerable produce was of wine, olives, figs, 
 and honey; w^ine was probably better in other places; but 
 the oil and honey were particularly excellent'*', the latter espe- 
 cially in the district of the mines^*% and upon Mount Hymet- 
 tus. The figs hkewise were very much esteemed. Even now 
 the keeping of the bees is carried on to a considerable extent in 
 Attica. The olive-trees make regular woods, and the wine is 
 considered wholesome'' ^ For the protection of this branch of 
 industry, laws were enacted that these products should not be 
 diminished, and that one person should not be injured by 
 another in raising them ; hence the ordinances of Solon with 
 regard to the keeping of bees'®* ; hence no olive-tree could be 
 rooted up, excepting that each proprietor was allowed to destroy 
 two in each year for public festivals, or for his own use in the case 
 of a death'"'. Many of these products of the soil were exported, 
 although, according to Plutarch^", Solon prohibited all export 
 of provisions, as might be seen from the first Table of the Laws 
 of Solon; but, fortunately, this writer afterguards contradicts 
 himself, when in another place he mentions the famous prohi- 
 bition to export figs as no more than probable^". The export- 
 ation of oil alone is said to have been permitted by Solon, as 
 Plutarch also remarks, and in this point his testimony is con- 
 firmed by examples '®^ As to the prohibition of the export of 
 
 '^^ Oiat. cont. Phsenipp. p. 1045, 12. 
 
 ^*» Pseud-^schin. Epist. 5. 
 
 i«° Strab. ix. p. 275. 
 
 ^®' See Wheler, Chandler, and other 
 travellers. Concerning oil 
 Meursius Fort. Att. chap. x. 
 
 comp. 
 
 '«^ Petit Leg. Att. v. 1, 6. 
 '" Demosth. cont. Macart. p. 1074. 
 ''* Solon. 24. 
 '** De Curiositate, ad fin. 
 i^« Plutarch Solon. 2, where Plato 
 is said to carry on a trade in oil ; and
 
 42 AGRICULTURE, AND [bK. I. 
 
 figs, I am entirely convinced that it did not exist in the times 
 of which we have any certain knowledge. All that occurs in 
 ancient writers upon this subject, only serves to explain the 
 meaning of the word sycophant. Plutarch himself ventures to 
 adopt it at the most for the very early times. If, however, the 
 ancients had possessed any account of such a law, that could be 
 at all depended upon, they would not speak in so vague and 
 indefinite a manner concerning the origin of this appellation. 
 If a prohibition ever did exist, it certainly was not caused by 
 the reason which is jocularly mentioned by Hume'^^, that the 
 Athenians thought their figs too delicious for foreign palates, 
 although Athenaeus^^^ nearly uses the same expression; but the 
 object of the measure must have been to increase the quantity 
 of figs in the country, while they were as yet very scarce in the 
 most ancient times. This view of the case may be formed from 
 the Scholiast upon Plato'", who dates the origin of the name of 
 sycophant at a period when this fruit was first discovered in 
 Attica, and did not grow in any other country. But the 
 account is far more probable which states that the sacred fig- 
 trees were robbed of their fruit during a famine, and that the 
 wrath of the gods being felt in consequence of this sacrilege, 
 accusations were brought against the suspected^"*'. In the same 
 manner, persons who injured the sacred olive-trees might be 
 subjected to heavy penalties, of which Lysias in his defence 
 concerning the sacred olive-trees, affords a remarkable instance. 
 Here then it would be impossible to understand a prohibition 
 of exportation, which can only exist with regard to articles 
 necessary for the consumption of the community, such as corn. 
 The keeping of cattle unquestionably existed to a consider- 
 
 althoiigli it refers to later times, the j pliauts ad Tlieoplirast. Char. 23, of. 
 
 law of Solon luay still have been in 
 force in reference to such cases. Petit 
 Leg. Alt. V. 5, 1, absurdly limits the 
 permission to export oil to the cruise 
 filled with oil given to the victors in 
 the Panathenaic games. 
 
 w Ut sup. p. 81. 
 
 '^^ iii. p. 74, E. Avhere see Casaubon. 
 The same writer treats of tlie Syco- 
 
 Ast. ad Plat, de Repub. p. 361, ed. 2. 
 Petit Leg. Att. v. 5, 2, does not give 
 any clear account of this point. To 
 the passages quoted by earlier writers 
 Lex. Seg. p. 304, may also be added. 
 
 '^9 P. 147, Ruhnk. cf. Schol. Aris- 
 toph. Plut. 874. 
 
 '70 Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 31.
 
 CH. VIII.] 
 
 NATIVE PRODUCTS OF ATTICA. 
 
 43 
 
 able extent : sheep and goats were the most numerous. From 
 the latter animal one of the four ancient tribes^ ^gicoreis, took 
 its name^ which^ from the time of Cleisthenes^ remained only 
 a borough; of the former there were many different breeds, 
 and particularly of the finest kinds '^^ In order to encourage 
 the keeping of sheep^ it was forbidden in a law of extreme 
 antiquity to kill them before they had lambed or been shorn' '^: 
 but this and similar regulations had been long abolished in the 
 time of Solon. Pigs were also kept, and of larger cattle, asses 
 and mules in tolerable quantities. Horses and horned cattle 
 were evidently scarce in early times. Philochorus'^^ mentions 
 a very ancient law which prohibited the killing of horned cattle ; 
 and the scarcity of horses is manifest from the early insignifi- 
 cance of the Athenian cavalry, which, after the establishment 
 of the Naucrarias, only amounted to 96 or 100 men, and was 
 not even in existence at the time of the battle of Marathon. 
 Subsequently horses and oxen were kept in sufficient quantities, 
 for which the pastures of Eubcea afforded great facilities. 
 
 The woodlands for the most part only supplied fire- 
 wood ; the ship-building was carried on with imported timber. 
 The fisheries were productive; the mines, in addition to 
 silver, yielded lead, metallic colours, coloured earths, per- 
 haps also copper; and the products of the Athenian foun- 
 dries were particularly esteemed. The quarries of Pentelus 
 and Hymettus furnished the most beautiful kinds of marble, 
 which were much exported to foreign parts'^*. Commercial 
 occupations were nowhere in great esteem among the an- 
 cient Greeks. Probably no person of ancient nobility ever 
 condescended to them, although conversely a manufacturer 
 might raise himself to the head of public affairs, such as Cleonj 
 Hyperbolus, and others. The early statesmen; however, encou- 
 raged industry, especially Solon, Themistocles, and Pericles, 
 
 ^''^ Demostli. cont. Euerg. et Mne- 
 sib. p. 1 155, 3, or whoever is the author 
 of this speech, which is called in ques- 
 tion by the ancients (see Harpocrat. in 
 V. rjTTjfievTjp), Athen. xii. p. 540, D. 
 
 '''^ Audrot. ap. Athen. ix. p. 375, C, 
 
 Philochorus ibid. i. p. 9, C Other 
 ancient laws to the same effect have 
 been collected by Petit v, 3. 
 
 ^73 Ap. Athen. ix. p. 375, C. 
 
 '7* Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 1.
 
 44 
 
 AGRICULTURE, AND 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 partly with the intention of improving the condition of the lower 
 classes, and partly of increasing the population of the city; as 
 well as advancing the cause of commerce, and of manning the 
 numerous fleets, by which, after the time of Themistocles, the 
 Athenians held the mastery of the sea'^'. And it was this cir- 
 cumstance that rendered the resident ahens indispensable for 
 Athens '% who carried on manufactures and commerce to a great 
 extent, and were bound to serve in the fleet. It even appears 
 that the useful arts were encouraged by honorary rewards^"; 
 though even by these means they could not gain in the public 
 estimation : they were prizes for the common people, for which 
 the higher ranks did not envy them. At the same time the 
 
 ^7* Proofs of this occur everywhere. 
 Diodorus (xi. 43) in particular ex- 
 presses himself very clearly with re- 
 gard to Themistocles. 
 
 ^76 Xenophon de Rep. Ath. i. 12. 
 The genuineness of this Essay stands 
 and falls with the other Treatise on the 
 State of the Lacedaemonians, which 
 Demetrius the Magnesian (ap. Diog. 
 Laert. ii. 57) abjudged from Xeno- 
 phon. But the Essay upon the Reve- 
 nues of Athens is so similar to those 
 two in style, that it must be included 
 in their condemnation ; and it is cer- 
 tainly possible to raise doubts against 
 the latter writing, which however I 
 consider as futile. The predilection 
 for Sparta which predominates in the 
 two first writings, is very like Xeno- 
 phon, who, even in his history, is the 
 constant eulogist of the Spartans, and 
 frequently allows his predilections to 
 give a colour to real facts. A certain 
 irony in the tone, which occurs in the 
 pamphlet upon the State of Athens, is 
 not very much in Xenophon's manner, 
 but it might have been easily produced 
 by particular circumstances and by the 
 nature of his subject. It should be 
 observed, that contradictions may be 
 discovered between tiiis writing and 
 the other upon the Revenues j thus in 
 Rep. Ath. i. 10, the freedom of the 
 
 aliens is foimd fault with, whereas in 
 the Treatise on the Revenues ( hap. 
 2) he recommends favouring them, 
 and lightening their burdens, together 
 with other discrepancies of the same 
 kind : but the difference of the times, 
 objects, and circumstances must be 
 taken into consideration, from which 
 these contradictions are easily ac- 
 counted for, if Xenophon wrote on the 
 State of Athens during his exile, and 
 on the Revenues after his recal, a 
 short time, as it is asserted, before Ms 
 death took place at Corinth. The 
 arguments also learnedly brought for- 
 ward by Schneider concerning the date 
 of his writing, which tend to prove it 
 not to be the production of Xenophon, 
 are not entirely tenable, as I have 
 shown in book iii. chap. 6, note. At 
 the same time I am willing to allow 
 that the genuineness of this and other 
 short writings of Xenophon is not suf- 
 ficiently established, and that the 
 Essay on the State of Athens may 
 easily have been written by another 
 author. All I wish to assert is, that 
 the arguments which have as yet been 
 brought against their genuineness, are 
 not sufficient, and that a farther in- 
 vestigation is necessary. 
 
 ^" SchoL Aristoph. Ran. 775.
 
 CH. VIII.] NATIVE PRODUCTS OF ATTICA, 
 
 45 
 
 respectable citizens, who had none of the high aristocratical 
 notions, like Pericles, Alcibiades, or Callias the son of Hippo- 
 nicus, (whose pride yielded in nothing to the haughtiness of the 
 modern nobility,) were not ashamed of superintending extensive 
 manufactories worked at their own expense. The inferior 
 citizens were as much reduced to the necessity of manual labour 
 as the poor aliens and slaves. It was only in times when the 
 balance had been turned in favour of the aristocracy, that mea- 
 sures of severity were brought forward ; as for example, Dio- 
 phantus proposed that all artizans should be made public 
 slaves'". There was again another reason why no restriction 
 could be imposed upon the freedom of industry, viz. the little 
 importance that was attached to it; an alien was allowed to 
 carry on any trade, although he was prohibited from holding 
 any property in land ; with regard indeed to sales in the market, 
 strangers were on a less advantageous footing than natives, as 
 they were obliged to pay a duty for permission to expose their 
 goods there. The law of Solon that men should not deal in 
 ointments ^^' was only founded on principles of education, in 
 order to withdraw men from womanish labours ; subsequently 
 however it became a dead letter, for ^schines the philosopher 
 had a maniifactory of ointments. 
 
 With this entire freedom of industry, with the large num- 
 bers of aliens and slaves, and the possibility of an extensive 
 market by means of foreign commerce, and with the magnitude 
 of the internal demand, which was increased by the resident 
 foreigners, all branches of industry flourished, and Athens con- 
 tained many manufactories, which employed a corresponding 
 
 '7° Petit, V. 6, 1. [The passage of 
 Aristotle's Politics, ii. 7. ad fin. which 
 alludes to the measure of Diophantus, 
 does not give it the extent which is 
 assigned to it in the text. Aristotle, 
 criticizing Plato's plan of a perfect 
 commonwealth, objects to Plato's pro- 
 posal that all the persons who labour 
 for the body of citizens are to be 
 public slaves ; and he then adds, that, 
 at aU events, if this is to be so, it 
 
 should resemble the practice at Epi- 
 damnus, and the arrangement for- 
 merly made by Diophantus at Athens. 
 This allusion is too concise to indicate 
 clearly the nature of the measure of 
 Diophantus. Diophantus, the author 
 of this measure, appears to have flou- 
 rished during the boyhood of Aristotle. 
 — Transl.] 
 
 =7» Petit, v. 6, 3.
 
 46 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 quantity of labourers. Athenian arms and other metallic 
 fabrics, implements and materials for dress and furniture, were 
 in great request; tanners, arm-smiths, lamp-makers, cloth- 
 weavers, even millers and bakers, who understood their art well, 
 lived in abundance^ ®°. With regard to the prices of commodi- 
 ties, it would be natural to suppose that they must have been 
 proportionally low, as all the labourers, and part even of the 
 overseers, were slaves ; as the rate of wages was moderate, and 
 there existed a complete freedom of industry; but to counter- 
 balance these causes there was the extensive exportation, which 
 together with the high rate of interest, and the proportionally 
 high profits, which the manufacturers and merchants obtained, 
 operated to force up the prices of commodities. At the same 
 time many articles, such as bread and clothing, were prepared 
 in most families at home, and not purchased from retail dealers. 
 
 Chapter IX. 
 
 Foreign Trade of Attica, 
 
 The commodities which Attica did not produce within her own 
 territory, were obtained by foreign commerce, and unless the 
 importation was prevented by some extraordinary obstacle, such 
 as war, there could be no danger of a scarcity, even in the case 
 of a failure of the crops, because it consumed the surplus pro- 
 duce of other countries^®\ Although not an island, yet it pos- 
 sessed all the advantages of insular position, that is, excellent 
 harbours conveniently situated, in which it received supplies 
 during all winds ; in addition to which it had sufficient facilities 
 for inland traffic : the intercourse with other countries was pro- 
 moted by the purity of the coin, as the merchant, not being 
 obliged to take a return freight, had the option of carrying out 
 bullion, although Athens abounded in commodities which would 
 meet with a ready sale'^*. For prohibitions to export money 
 
 '^•^ Only to quote one passage, see 
 Xeuoph. Mem. Socr. ii. 7,3 — G. "With 
 regard to the exportation of manufac- 
 tured goods, see Wolf ad Leptin. p. 
 
 252. 
 
 ii. G. 
 
 Cf. Xenoph. de Rcpub. Ath. 
 Xenoph. de Vectig. 1, 7, 3, 2. •
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 
 
 47 
 
 were unknown in ancient times, and are only compatible 
 with the use of bills of exchange. If a stagnation in trade was 
 not produced by war or piracy, all the products of foreign coun- 
 tries came to Athens ; and articles which in other places could 
 hardly be obtained singly, were collected together at the 
 Piraeus' ^^ Besides the corn, the costly whines, iron, brass, and 
 other objects of commerce which came from all the regions of 
 the Mediterranean, they imported from the coasts of the Black 
 Sea, slaves, timber for ship-building, salt-fish, honey, wax, tar, 
 wool, rigging, leather, goat-skins, &c.; from Byzantium, Thrace, 
 and Macedonia, timber, slaves, and salt-fish ; also slaves from 
 Thessaly, whither they came from the interior ; and carpets and 
 fine wool from Phrygia and Miletus'^*. "All the luxiu-ies,^^ 
 says Xenophon'^^, "of Sicily, of Italy, Cyprus, Lydia, the 
 Pontus, and the Peloponnese, Athens, by her empire of the sea, 
 is able to collect into one spot:" to this far extended inter- 
 course the same author even attributes a mixture of all dialects 
 which prevailed at Athens, and the admission of barbarous 
 words into the language of common life. On the other hand, 
 Athens conveyed to different regions the products of her own 
 soil and labour ; in addition to which the Athenian merchants 
 trafficked in commodities which they collected in other coun- 
 tries. Thus they took up wine from the islands and shores of 
 the ^gean Sea, at Peparethos, Cos, Thasos, Mende, Scione, 
 and elsewhere, and transported it to the Pontus^°^ The trade 
 in books appears alone to have made but small advances in 
 Greece, a branch of industry which was more widely extended 
 in the Roman empire after the reign of Augustus. There was, 
 it is true, a book market [tcl ^l/SXay^'^ at Athens, and books 
 were exported to the Pontus and to Thrace '^^; but there can be 
 no doubt that the books meant were merely blank volumes. 
 The trade in manuscripts was in the time of Plato so little com- 
 
 ^^ Thucyd. ii. 38, Isocrat. Paneg. 
 p. 34, ed. Hall. 
 
 '^* Upon most of these points see 
 Barthelemy, Anacaars. torn. iv. chap. 
 65, Wolf ad Leptin. p. 252. 
 
 '" De Rep. Ath. 2, 7. 
 
 '^^ Demosth. c. Laerit. p. 935, 6. 
 
 ^^^ Pollux ix. 47, and the commen- 
 tators. 
 
 ^"^ Xenoph. Cyr. Exped. vii. 5, 14, 
 and the commentators.
 
 48 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 men, that Hermodorus, who sold the books of this writer in 
 Sicily, gave occasion to a proverb, " Hermodorus trades in 
 writings' °%^^ at a subsequent period, while Zeno the Stoic was 
 still a youth, dealers in manuscripts are also mentioned as 
 having been at Athens''**'. The merchant-vessels appear to have 
 been of considerable size; not to quote an extraordinary 
 instance, we find in Demosthenes'®' a vessel of this kind, 
 which, besides the cargo, the slaves, and the ship's crew, carried 
 300 free inhabitants. 
 
 Athens had many regulations for the protection of trade, 
 and for the maintenance of the commercial police. Among 
 the officers belonging to this branch of the public service we 
 may mention the overseers of the harbour (eTrcfieXrjTal tov 
 kfiTTOplov), ten men annually appointed by lot'" ; the Agora- 
 nomi, five in the city and as many in the Pireeus'*^; the 
 Metronomi, who had the inspection of the measures, ten in 
 the city and five in the Piraeus''* ; and the Prometretee, pro- 
 bably subordinate to the latter officers, who measured com 
 
 ^^» Clcer. Epist. ad Attic. xiiL 21. 
 Zenobius and Suidas in v. 'Koyoio-iv 
 *'Epfi68cc)pos f/xTTopeufrat. 
 
 ^^° Diog. Laert. in Vit. Zenonis. 
 
 ^9' Cont. Phorm. p. 910, 12. 
 
 1^2 Demosth. cont. Lacrit. p. 941, 
 15 ; Orat. cont. Theocrin. p. 1324, 10 ; 
 Dinarch. cont. Aristog. p. 81, 82; 
 Lex. Seg. p. 255; and what Sigonius 
 iv. 3, has upon the Constitution of 
 Athens. 
 
 '^^ Aristot. ap. Hai-pocrat. in v. 
 dyopavofiot, &c. 
 
 "■* The passage in Harpocration is 
 as follows : r](rav 8e tov apiBpov nevre- 
 KaibfKa, fls p.€V rov Ueipaia Sexa, rrevre 
 ^ els acTTv. I read it the contrary 
 way, els pev tov Tleipaia nevTC, fieica S' 
 etff aoTv. The same correction shoiild 
 be made in Suidas in v. perpovopoi and 
 in Photius. For what Meursius and 
 KQster say upon the passage in Suidas 
 is highly absurd. In the same man- 
 ner there were ten Sitophylaces in the 
 city and five in the Piraeeus: see be- 
 
 low chap. 15. Both divisions must 
 necessarily have been closely con- 
 nected, and for this reason the simi- 
 larity of the number is also probable. 
 In addition to this, the merchants were 
 obliged to bring two-thirds of the corn 
 from the harbour into the city, which 
 fact agrees completely with my emen- 
 dation. The Lex. Seg. p. 278, cer- 
 tainly has in v. perpovopoi, deKa tov 
 apiOpov, (cv nevTe pev rjcrav iv t<o Ilfi- 
 paieX, irevTc S' ev acrrei, nearly as Pho- 
 tius in the first article. But although 
 it might appear more natural that 
 their number should agree with that 
 of the Agoranomi, and seem singular 
 that there should have been ten in the 
 city and five in the Piraeus, this very 
 circumstance makes it more credible 
 that my hypothesis is true, and that 
 the statement in the Lex. Seg. is the 
 arbitrary alteration of a grammarian 
 according to what appeared to him the 
 most natural. A different account is 
 given by Kuhn ad Poll. iv. 1(>7.
 
 CH. IX.] FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 49 
 
 and other grain for hire'''\ Upon the whole, there was suffi- 
 cient attention paid to weights and measures ; as may in part 
 he seen from a valuable fragment of a decree upon this subject, 
 which has fortunately come down to our days^®^. 
 
 Credit was at a low ebb in Greece, although we find that there 
 were large firms in all the different Grecian states, which were 
 possessed of extensive credit, and were able to raise money on 
 the single security of their name'®^ Merchants belonging to par- 
 ticular cities, as the Phaselitans for example, were in bad repute 
 on account of their want of honesty'^*. The absence of credit 
 was supplied by security or bail ; which, according to the laws 
 of Athens, was in force for one year'®®. The severity of the 
 laws relating to debtors contributed materially to the support 
 of credit, for the Athenians knew well how important these 
 laws were to commerce and industry^"". "In the Athenian 
 laws,^^ says Demosthenes, " there are many excellent protections 
 for the creditor; for commerce proceeds not from the bor- 
 rower but from the lender ; without whose assistance no vessel, 
 no captain, no passenger can stir.^^ Even a citizen, who in the 
 capacity of a merchant, withdrew from a creditor a pledge for a 
 sum vested in bottomry, could be punished with loss of life*"'. 
 
 No less severe were the regulations against false accu- 
 sers of merchants and captains of vessels^"^ Their disputes 
 were heard before the commercial court of the Nautodicee, 
 where the Thesmothetse introduced the causes^""* ; in law-suits 
 between citizens of different nations, by virtue of particular 
 agreements, there existed an appeal from one state to the 
 other^°\ As early as in. the time of Lysias, the Nautodicee, 
 
 **' Harpocrat. in v. TrpofMeTprjToi, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 290, &c. 
 
 '»« See Boeckh. Corp. Inscr. No. 123. 
 
 ^^ Orat. cont. Theocrin. p. 1324, 
 1325, cf. inf. iii. 10. 
 203 Pqj. ^.jjg gakg Qf brevity I refer 
 
 '^7 Demosth, cont. Polycl. p. 1224, 3. | to Sigonius R. A. iv. 3 ; Petit v. 5, 9 ; 
 '^» Demostli. cont. Lacrit. init. Mattliise :Misc. Pliilol. vol. i. p. 247. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. cont. Apatur. p. 901, 7. 
 
 ^^ Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 958. 
 
 '^"^ Demosth. cont. Phorm. p. 922. 
 Dilatory debtors were also liable to 
 imprisonment, only however in com- 
 
 The Lex. Seg. also has an article upon 
 this subject, as well as Photius, p. 212. 
 It is worthy of remark that the ypacpi) 
 ^evlas could also be brought before 
 this court. 
 
 mercial cases. See Hudtwalker vo?i i ''"* These are the diKoi ana avp- 
 den Diateten, p. 152 sq. Qokav. 
 
 E
 
 50 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. [bK. J, 
 
 having been appointed to their office by lot, assembled in the 
 month Gamelion, in order to sit during the winter, when 
 navigation ceased''', that the merchants and captains of vessels 
 might not be impeded in the pursuit of their business. Ad- 
 vantageous as this regulation vras, it did not obviate all the 
 inconveniences to ^yhich traders were liable ; for if the cause 
 was not decided in the course of the winter, either the parties 
 were obliged to prosecute it in summer to the prejudice of 
 their business, or the case stood over till the following winter, 
 and was heard before other judges. For this reason Xenophon 
 proposed to establish a prize for the officer of the harbour who 
 should pronounce the most rapid and just decisions of com- 
 mercial causes^"^ ; and in fact soon afterwards, in the time of 
 Philip**'^, this evil was checked by the introduction of the 
 monthly suits {efifJLrjvot hUaL), to which all causes concerning 
 trade, eranus, do\mes, and mines belonged^''^ These were 
 heard in the six winter months, so that the merchants might 
 quickly obtain their rights and set saiP"^ ; and a cause could 
 not, as some have supposed, be protracted through this whole 
 time, but it was necessary that it should be decided within the 
 term of a month^'". 
 
 Lastly, the Greeks tolerated a species of consul in the 
 person of the Proxenus of each state, who was considered as 
 the representative of his country, and was bound to protect 
 the citizens who traded at the place. If, for example, an inha- 
 bitant of Heraclea died at any place, the Proxenus of Heraclea 
 was, by virtue of his office, obliged to make enquiries concerning 
 the property which he left behind him^'^ On one occasion, 
 when an inhabitant of Heraclea died at Argos, tlie Proxenus of 
 Heraclea received his property"' ^ 
 
 ^■^ Lysias Trepi Stjixcs. ddiK. p. 593. 
 ="'6 De Vectig. 3. 
 
 ^7 Vid. Orat. de Ilaloneso, p. 70, 
 18, sqq. 
 
 end of vol. ii.) 
 
 209 Demosth. cont. Apatur. p. 900, 
 3, cf p. 9fiG, 17; Petit V. 5, 9. 
 
 ^'° Vid. Orat. de Haloneso : Lex. 
 
 '^•'s Pollux viii. G3, 101. Suidas in Seg. ; and Petit ut sup. ; Salmas. de 
 V. efifXTjuoi bUai from llarpocr. in the i M. U. xvi. p. 691. 
 same word, Lex. Seg. p. 237. That ^^ Demosth. cont. Callipp. p. 1237 
 this is true of causes relating to mines, 16. 
 I have shown in my Dissertation upon -'=^ Ihid. p. 128?}, 27. 
 the Silver ]Mines of Lauriou, (at thp
 
 CH. IX.] FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 51 
 
 Among the many proposals for the advancement of com- 
 merce which Xenophon makes in his Treatise upon the 
 Revenues, there is nowhere an exhortation to restore the 
 freedom of trade : either this was not one of the points which 
 lay within the knowledge of antiquity, or it must have existed 
 without any limit. The latter supposition is nearly maintained 
 byHeeren*^^: ^^they were ignorant/^ says he, ^^ of a balance of 
 trade, and thus all the violent measures that flow from it naturally 
 remained unknown. They had custom duties as well as our- 
 selves ; but these were intended only to increase the revenues 
 of the state, and not, as in modern nations, by excluding 
 certain articles, to give a particular direction to the course of 
 industry. You will find no prohibition to export raw produce, 
 no encouragement of manufactures at the cost of the agricul- 
 tural classes. In this sense then there was a complete freedom 
 of industry, of commerce, and of intercourse. And this was 
 the general practice. At the same time, where everything was 
 determined by circumstances, not by any theory, persons may 
 find individual exceptions, perhaps discover particular cases in 
 which the state may for a time have assumed to itself a mono- 
 poly. But yet what a vade difference is there between this and 
 our mercantile and restrictive system.^^ 
 
 I am ready to acknowledge that there is a great deal of 
 truth in these remarks; but the other side of the question 
 must also be considered. According to the principles of the 
 ancients, which were not merely scientific, but were recog- 
 nised by the whole of the people, and deeply rooted in the 
 nature of the Greeks, the state embraced and governed all 
 relations between man and man. Not in Crete and Lace- 
 daemon alone, two states completely closed up and unsus- 
 ceptible of free trade, but generally throughout^ the whole 
 of Greece, and even under the free government of Athens, 
 the poorest as well as the richest citizen was convinced 
 that the state had the right of claiming the whole property of 
 every individual. Any restriction in the transfer of this pro- 
 
 Ideen Uber die Politik, den Verkelir iind den Handel der alten Welt, 
 vol. iii. p. 283. 
 
 E 2
 
 52 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. [bK. I. 
 
 perty, regulated according to circumstances, was looked upon 
 as just ; nor could it properly be considered an infringement 
 of justice, before the security of persons and property was held 
 to be the sole object of government; a light under which it 
 never was viewed by any of the ancients. On the contrary, 
 all intercourse and commerce were considered as being under 
 the direction of the community, inasmuch as they originally 
 owed their existence to the establishment of a regular political 
 union : and upon the same basis was founded the right of the state 
 to regulate trade, or even to participate in the profits of it. Any 
 person who dissented from these principles was not a member 
 of the state, and was at liberty to detach himself from it. > 
 
 It was upon the same principle that the national mono- 
 polies were founded, which appear to have been not unfre- 
 quent in Greece, although of short duration; their produc- 
 tiveness had been tried in the cases of private individuals 
 who had obtained them by engrossing particular articles^"*. 
 It can, however, be safely asserted, that no republic ever 
 demanded of its citizens that they should furnish commo- 
 dities to the state in specified quantities and at prices 
 arbitrarily fixed at a low rate, with a view to secure to itself a 
 monopoly; such a demand could only have been enforced in 
 countries under the government of a tyrant. The monopoly of 
 lead, which Pythocles proposed to the Athenians, injured no 
 proprietor of mines, provided it was exported: the producers 
 were to receive the same price from the state, at which they had 
 before sold it*^'. Equally innocent was the banking monopoly 
 which the Byzantians in a pecuniary embarrassment sold to 
 a private individual^ ^^ The proceeding of the Selymbriani in a 
 similar difficulty was probably less defensible, who seized the 
 whole stock of corn at a fixed price, with the exception of a 
 quantity sufficient for the yearly consumption of each indi- 
 vidual, and then sold it at a higher price with permission to 
 export, which before had not been granted ^'^ But how many 
 kinds of monopolies may there not have been in Greece ! 
 
 ^'^ Cf. Arist. Pol. i. 7. 1 nomics attributed to Aristotle, c. 
 
 ^'* See above, chap. vi. ! 17. 
 
 ^^^ See the second book of the (Eco- \ ^^' Ibid.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 
 
 53 
 
 Probably it was then a principle in politics, that states should 
 avail themselves of these aids when under the pressure of pecu- 
 niary distress^'®. In addition to this there are abundant proofs 
 that the exportation and importation were regulated according 
 to the exigencies and interests of the state ; which is by no 
 means consistent with perfect freedom of trade. 
 
 Aristotle *^^ lays down five principles of policy as the most 
 important, viz.: finance, peace, and war, the safeguard of the 
 country, importation and exportation, and legislation; men- 
 tioning at the same time that " with regard to importation and 
 exportation, it is necessary to know how large a supply of provi- 
 sions the state requires, and what proportion of them can be 
 produced in the country and what imported, and what imports 
 and exports are necessar}^ for the state, in order that commercial 
 treaties and agreements may be concluded wdth those of whom 
 the state must make use for this purpose.^^ Trade was thus 
 an object of national policy; whence various restrictions or 
 preferences must necessarily have arisen. 
 
 Solon is related by Plutarch to have laid the exportation 
 of all products of the soil except oil, under a malediction, 
 which the Archon was obliged to pronounce or to pay a fine 
 of a hundred drachmas ^^^: although the law was not in my 
 opinion so general as here stated^*', yet the main fact is 
 unquestionable; and, considering the liberal disposition of 
 Solon, is the more remarkable. The export of corn was always 
 prohibited in Attica^". Similar laws doubtless existed in other 
 states, for example the Selymbriani prohibited the exportation 
 of corn, if not always, at least in time of scarcity *^^ There 
 were also at Athens many commodities of which the exportation 
 was prohibited (airopprjra), such as timber, tar, wax, rigging, 
 and leathern bottles, articles which were particularly important 
 for the building and equipment of the fleet ^^*. It may indeed 
 
 2 '8 Cf. Arist. Pol. i. 11. 
 2'9 Rhetor, i. 4. 
 "« Plutarch. Sol. 24. 
 ^^* See above, chap. viii. 
 222 uipian. ad Demosth. cont. Ti- 
 mocr. p. 822. 
 
 '^'^' Pseud-Aiistot. (Econ. ii. 17- 
 
 ^^* Upon this point see Aristoph. 
 Ran. 365, 367, and the Scholiast, 
 Spanheim upon this passage, and Ca- 
 saubon ad Theophrast. Char. 23. Con- 
 cerning the leather-bottles (ao-zcco/xara) 
 conip. besides the Scholiast of Ari- 
 stophanes, the Etoraologist, Suidas,and
 
 54 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. [bK. I. 
 
 be supposed that this prohibition only existed against the Pelo- 
 ponnesians during the continuance of war ^"; but how often did 
 Greece enjoy the blessings of peace ? and even in the time of 
 Theophrastus, the exportation of timber^ i, e, of timber for 
 ship-building, was still prohibited, being only allowed to parti- 
 cular individuals free of duty"^ 
 
 It is obvious that war was necessarily attended with certain 
 restrictions and limitations ; for example the manufactories of 
 arms at Athens supplied the consumption of many nations ; it 
 was natural therefore that laws should be directed against those 
 who provided the enemy with arms; thus Timarchus decreed, that 
 whoever furnished Philip either with arms or tackle for ships 
 should be punished with death ^*''. But in addition to these 
 restrictions, even the importation of some commodities was occa- 
 sionally prohibited in time of war ; as for example of Boeotian 
 lamp-wicks, of which the real reason cannot be, as Casaubon con- 
 cluded from the jokes of Aristophanes ^^^, that the Athenians were 
 afraid of these lamp-wicks causing a conflagration, but that all 
 commodities imported from Bceotia were excluded, for the pur- 
 pose of harassing this country by a stoppage of all intercourse, as 
 indeed may be seen from another passage in the play just alluded 
 to^^^ In like manner Pericles, according to the Acharnians of 
 the same poet^^", and the testimonies of many other writers, 
 had excluded the Megarians from all intercourse with Attica, 
 in order to injure them. 
 
 Upon the whole, war was as much carried on by impe- 
 ding commerce as by force of arms, and by her dominion of 
 the sea Athens obtained the means of exercising a continual 
 despotism over trade. " No state,^^ observes Xenophon, ^' can 
 
 Thomas Magister in v. OvXokos. [The 
 passage of Theoplirastiis appears to 
 refer to the exportation of timber from 
 Macedonia, not from Attica. See 
 Schneider's note on the passage, cited 
 in Ast's edition, p. 205, and compare 
 below, note 450. — Transl.] 
 
 ^^^ Which one slioiild also be led to 
 suppose from Aristophanes and his 
 Scholiast ut sup. and from Aristoph. 
 E.]. 27«. 
 
 2^« Theophiust. Char. 23. 
 
 ^=^7 Demosth. de fals. Leg. p. 433, 4. 
 See the note to Petit's Leg. Att. 
 p. 517, ed. Wessel. 
 
 ^^^ Aristoph. Acharn. 01 G, and the 
 Scholiast, Casaubon ut sup. 
 
 2^« Acharn. 860 sqq. 
 
 ^^" See more particularly the argu- 
 ment to this Play, Thucyd, i. 130 ; 
 Plutaich. Pcricl. 30 ; Diod. xii. 39 sqq.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTlCA. 
 
 55 
 
 ever export anything, if it be not submissive to the masters 
 of the sea; upon them depends all the exportation of the 
 surplus produce of other nations ^^^" They laid an embargo 
 upon all vessels, seized, and detained or captured merchant- 
 vessels, even such as the state had no right to interfere with ; 
 and to recover by the prize courts the goods which had been 
 unlawfully lost, was a matter of extreme difficulty. That these 
 measures of the Athenians produced the greatest hatred against 
 them, cannot excite surprise. Even the Spartans made a 
 protest against the Megarian decree ; its non-repeal was the 
 immediate pretext of the Peloponnesian war. 
 
 These examples, although not applicable to a state of peace, 
 prove at least, that the Athenians did not shrink from any 
 restriction of commerce, so long as it appeared profitable to them ; 
 and from this it may be fairly concluded, that at times too when 
 there was a cessation from war, they provided for their real or sup- 
 posed interests by various regulations which w^ere inconsistent 
 with freedom of trade. They framed restrictive laws for the 
 purpose of forcing the supply of those commodities which were 
 necessary for the consumption of the country; or which should 
 be brought to the market in the port of Athens, in order to be 
 there sold, that by these means Athens might become a general 
 emporium. 
 
 Some of these regulations are extraordinarily severe. No 
 inhabitant, for example, was allowed to carry corn anywhere 
 but to the harbour of Athens; those who violated this law 
 were subject to a Phasis or an Eisangelia^^^ In the same 
 manner it was fixed what portion of the corn of each cargo 
 
 231 Xenoph. de Eep. Ath. ii. 3, 11, 
 12. The words npos 5e tovtois aXXocre 
 ayeiv ovK edaovaiv, oltivcs avriizaKoL 
 f}fi2v €la\i/, rj ov xPW^VTaL rfj daXaTTrj, 
 are extremely difficult to understand, 
 and certainly have not been under- 
 stood by the commentators; but yet 
 they do not appear corrupt. The sense 
 is, " The states, from which we re- 
 ceive imports, will not permit our ad- 
 versaries to export for their own use 
 the materials necessary for ship build- 
 
 ing, oj- they will lose by that means 
 the use of the sea." The subject to 
 edaovaiv and xPW^^'''^'- ^^ eKelvoi, 
 which refers to the preceding napa 
 fiev Toi), napa 6e tov. The words 6m- 
 ves dvTL7ra\oi rjplv dalv are to be taken 
 instead of the accusative to ciyeiv, just 
 as if it stood rrpos de tovtois iKelvoi ovk 
 idaovariv aXKoae riyeiv tovs rjpiv clvtl- 
 Tii'ikovs, rj ov ;^p]7<70i/rat rfj &a\dTTrj. 
 '^■^- See chap. xv.
 
 5S FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. [bK. I. 
 
 which had arrived in harbour, should be retained in the city 
 of Athens, as will be presently shown. There was also an 
 exceedingly oppressive regulation, that no Athenian or alien 
 resident in Attica should lend money upon a vessel which did 
 not return to Athens with a cargo of corn or other commo- 
 dities*". If indeed we listen to Salmasius"*, this law refers 
 only to the corn trade, and means no more than that it was not 
 permitted to lend money for the purpose of buying corn in 
 other countries, except upon the condition that the com should 
 be imported into Athens : this supposition is, however, mani- 
 festly devoid of foundation. The meaning of the law is, that 
 money could not be lent upon any ship which did not return to 
 Athens with corn ; but if these were all the provisions of the 
 law, no money could have been lent on bottomry at all, except 
 upon vessels employed in the corn trade. Since then this sup- 
 position leads to an absurdity, it is manifest that we do not 
 possess the law in a complete state. And this in fact is suffi- 
 ciently pointed out in the speech of Demosthenes against 
 Lacritus ; and corn, as being the most important article, was 
 only first and expressly named. In several places it is distinctly 
 stated, that it was not lawful to lend money which was to be sent 
 to any foreign port, without corn being particularly specified '*^^. 
 In the agreement of bottomry given in the speech of 
 Demosthenes against Lacritus (to which case this very law is 
 applied), it is not fixed that either corn or anything else should 
 be taken as a return-cargo ; and the debtor himself affirmed that 
 he had intended to return to Athens with a cargo of salt meat 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. cont. Lacrit. p. 941, 
 9 — 20, from the Law, ^Apyvpiov be fir) 
 e^elpai cKdovvai 'Adr^vaitov Kal tcov fie- 
 
 TOIKCOV TOiV *A6T]UT]ai flCTOlKOVUTCOU fJ.7j- 
 
 8lv), ^lr]^€ (ou ovToi Kvpioi. elaiv, elsvuvv 
 rjTis av fiT] peXXr] u^eii; arlrov ^ ABi^va^c, 
 Ka\ ToKka TO. yeypupfxepa nepl eKaaTov 
 avTcov. The last words show that many 
 other specific provisions followed which 
 the Orator omits, and in these no doubt 
 tlie other commodities were either in- 
 dividually or generally stated. 
 "* De .^I. U. V. p. 193 sqq. 
 
 ^^ Cont. Lacrit. ut sup. kuI S1V7 
 avTO) pr) earoi nepl tov apyvplov, o av 
 iKb(o aXkoae tttj rj 'A^r/i/a^e. Demosth. 
 cont. Dionysodor. p. 1284, 15. on ovk 
 av davcLcraipev els erepov epnopiou ovdiv 
 uXk' T} els ^Adrjvas. The passage iu 
 the speech against Lacritus p. 941, 15, 
 edv de tis e>c8&) napa raCr', eivai ttjv 
 (fidaiv Ka\ TT]v dnoypafjir^v tov dpyvpiov 
 TTpos Tovs eTTipeXrjTdSf Ka6a nepl rrjs 
 vea>s KOI TOV (tItov e'ipt]Tai, kuto. Tavra, 
 proves nothing against my assertion 
 for many reasons.
 
 CH. IX.] FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 6? 
 
 and Coan wine'^* : nor in any similar document is the species 
 of the commodities ever fixed which are to be taken as a return 
 cargo, but the only stipulations we find are \nth regard to the 
 security, and that the return-cargo should be of equal value 
 with the original freight. Lastly, how could it have been pos- 
 sible to specify the goods which were to be taken up as a return- 
 cargo, since the merchant would necessarily be guided in his 
 selection by the state of the market, and no certain calculation 
 could be made beforehand ? We must therefore allow, that in 
 general money could not be lent at Athens upon any ship or 
 its 'cargo, except on the condition of its returning to that city, 
 in order that no Athenian property might be employed to the 
 profit of a foreign trading town. This is not inconsistent with 
 the permission to lend money only for the time requisite for 
 the voyage to a particular place, without including the return 
 (ereSoTrXovs'). If the master of a vessel had borrowed money 
 for the time of his voyage from Athens to Rhodes, and instead 
 of not paying the money till he returned to Athens, if he was 
 obliged to repay it immediately upon his arrival at Rhodes, it 
 does not follow from this that he was not compelled to return ; 
 by law he was bound to do so, just as much as if the money 
 had been lent him until his return to Athens. The sole differ- 
 ence is, that in the former case the creditor was only exposed 
 to the risk of the passage outwards, in the latter, of the passage 
 inwards as welP^^ Money too could only be lent for the time 
 of the passage outwards, upon the condition of the vessel 
 returning to Athens : it was only absolutely prohibited when 
 the ship was not to return. It should also be remembered, that 
 heavy punishments were laid upon the violation of this law. 
 
 As to the laws relating to money lent out on other kinds 
 of security, no complaint could be made. Those who failed to 
 
 236 
 
 P. 933, 15. ! the voyage fiom Athens to Eg}i)t, aiid 
 
 *•'"' To this view of the subject the 
 passage in Deinosth. cont. Uionysod. 
 p. 1284, 8 — 20, cannot be opposed, for 
 if rightly understood, it completely 
 agrees •with it. Dionysodorus and 
 Parmeniscus wish to borrow monev for 
 
 from tlience to Rhodes ; it is therefore 
 a €T€p67rXovs without any obligation to 
 return, to which the lenders naturally 
 would not consent. Compare also 
 upon the questions relating to this 
 subject, book i. chap. 23.
 
 58 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA 
 
 [bk. 
 
 pay could be prosecuted by a Pliasis''^^; and the borrower, if 
 he did not return, could be punished with loss of life"^ If 
 the Athenians imposed such restrictions upon trade, it may be 
 conceived how the laws of other states were constituted. In 
 -^gina and Argos, Athenian manufactures appear to have been 
 in early times prohibited, although upon a pretended religious 
 motive, and on the immediate occasion for sacred purposes^^". 
 
 In the inland traffic, too, there was not by any means unre- 
 stricted freedom ; nor indeed did it consist with the principles 
 of the ancients, among whom the police mixed itself with every 
 thing, although the mode of its interference differed from that 
 which prevails in modern states. Assize regulations were not 
 unknown. In the time of Aristophanes the government of 
 Athens on one occasion reduced the price of salt to a fixed 
 rate ; which, however, was not long retained, probably because 
 it caused a deficiency in the supply of that article*"". In corn 
 we certainly find a great freedom of prices; yet engrossing 
 was restrained within certain limits. Retail dealing in the 
 market was originally interdicted to foreigners according to the 
 rigour of the law ; instances however occur of its being permit- 
 ted upon the payment of a duty, which is different from the 
 protection money of the resident aliens^"*^. What is here said 
 must not however be referred to the wholesale trade in the 
 harbour ; this in a great measure owed its existence to foreign- 
 ers, who exposed samples of their goods at a particular place 
 called Deigma^''^ for the convenience of the buyers who came 
 there from all regions to purchase commodities. 
 
 The prices of commodities could not, however, have been 
 much enhanced by these restrictions, especially as the custom- 
 
 ^^^ Demostli, cont. Lacrit. \\t sup. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. cont. Dioiiysod. p. 
 1205, 8 sqq. as tlie context sIioavs. 
 
 ''"" Ilcrod. V. 08. 
 
 '•^^' Aristoph. Eccl. SOD, and the 
 Scholiast. 
 
 ^'"^ Demosth. cont. Eul)ulid. p. 1.308, 
 9, p. 1309,5, Avliere this is called ^(viku 
 
 '^*^ Lysias Fragui. p. 31. Aristoph. 
 
 Eq. 975, and Schol. Demosth. cont. 
 Lacrit. p. 932, 20, cont. Polycl. p. 1214. 
 18, Ilarpoc. in v. delyfia, Pollux ix. 
 34, and there Jungennan coni])are 
 Casaub. ad Tlieoph. Char. 23, also 
 Lex. Seg. p. 237. Tlie Deigma at 
 Rhodes is mentioned by Polybius v. 
 69. The specimens themselves were 
 also called Deigma, Plutarch. Demosth. 
 23.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 FOREIGN TRADE OF ATTICA. 
 
 59 
 
 duties were very moderate ; but they were raised by the great 
 profit which the merchants obtained. That the rate of profits 
 was high, is sufficiently proved by the high rate of interest on 
 money lent upon bottomry (fenus nauticum), in which 30 per 
 cent, for one summer was not unfrequently paid. Hume's 
 remark^^^ that a high rate of interest and profit is an infaUible 
 sign, that industry and trade are still in their infancy, applies 
 with the greatest force to the ancient times of the Grecian 
 nations, and in some measure to that of Pericles, and the period 
 immediately succeeding. A Samian ship, which, as Herodo- 
 tus*^^ relates, had by accident made its way from Egypt to 
 Tartessus in Iberia, at a time when no Grecians, not even the 
 Phocseans, traded there, gained upon one cargo sixty talents ; 
 since the tithe to the goddess Hera amounted to six talents, 
 probably it had received silver at a low rate in exchange for the 
 goods carried out^^^ Greek merchants had never made a 
 greater profit, with the exception only of Sostratus of ^gina, 
 with whom no one could in this respect enter into comparison. 
 The value of the cargo of the Samian ship cannot now be ascer- 
 tained, as the quantity of goods on board different vessels was 
 very various ; we find instances of cargoes which did not exceed 
 two talents in value, but larger sums are met with ; thus a ship 
 of Naucratis, mentioned in Demosthenes, was valued at nine 
 and a half talents^"*^. In the time of Lysias also, an Athenian 
 vessel bound for the Adriatic is said to have made so large a 
 profit upon its cargo, of the value of two talents, that it doubled 
 the principaP'\ It is of course evident that the retail traders 
 [KCLTTriXoL) obtained likewise a very large profit on the goods 
 which they sold, if we take into consideration the high rate of 
 interest. 
 
 ^** Essays, p. 222. 
 ^^' Herod, iv. 152. 
 ''^^ Compare what Diodorus 
 says of the Phasnicians. 
 
 35, 
 
 2'7 Demosth. cent. Timocr. p. 696 
 and passim. 
 
 '^^^ Lysias cont. Diogit. p. 908.
 
 60 CHEAPNESS OF COMMODITIES [bK. I. 
 
 Chapter X. 
 Cheapness of Commodities in Ancient Greece. 
 
 I F allowance is made for accidental variation in different places, 
 it may be stated that in the ancient world the necessaries of 
 life were upon the whole cheaper than at the present time ; but 
 in individual cases many examples of the contrary occur. The 
 chief reasons of the former phenomenon are the smaller quan- 
 tity of money in circulation, the unusual fruitfulness of the 
 southern regions in which the Greeks either dwelt or traded — 
 regions, which though now neglected, were at that period in a 
 state of the highest cultivation — and the impossibility of export- 
 ation to distant lands, which had little or no intercourse with 
 the countries upon the Mediterranean. The latter is in parti- 
 cular the cause of the great cheapness of wine. The abundant 
 quantity of this article which was produced in almost all the 
 southern regions, was not distributed over so large a space of 
 the earth as is the case at present. 
 
 It is to be observed, however, that in considering the 
 general scale of prices in ancient states, the difference of time 
 and place must be well weighed. In Rome and in Athens, 
 at the most flourishing periods of these states, commodities 
 were not so cheap as in Upper Italy and Lusitania. In 
 Upper Italy, even in the time of Polybius*^% the Sicilian 
 medimnus of wheat, which was the same as the Attic, being 
 somewhat less than one and a half English bushel, frequently 
 sold for only four oboli (eight asses), i. e, about sixpence, 
 the medimnus of barley for half this sum, the metretes of 
 wine, about ten wine-gallons, for the same price as the barley! 
 Travellers used not, as in other places, to agree with the inn- 
 keepers for the price of each article, but only stipulated how 
 much they should give in the gross for the whole consumption 
 of an individual, and the sum demanded was generally a half 
 
 2i9 polyb. 1, 15. Polybius has \ rius equal to the drachma. He thus 
 changed the asses into oboli, reckoning i takes the Roman coins a small fraction 
 two asses to an obolus, and the deua- | too high.
 
 CH. X.] 
 
 IN ANCIENT GREECE. 
 
 61 
 
 as or quarter obolus, and seldom exceeded this rate. In Lusi- 
 tania, according to the same historian*'^ the Sicilian medimnus 
 of barley cost a drachma, of wheat nine Alexandrian oboli, which 
 appear to have been something less than the Attic"'; the 
 metretes of wine the same as the barley; a kid of moderate 
 size an obolus, a hare the same, a lamb three and four oboli, 
 a fat pig, weighing a hundred minas, five oboli, a sheep two, a 
 draught ox ten, a calf five drachmas, a talent of figs, about 
 fifty pounds, three oboli ; game had hardly any value, but was 
 included gratis in other bargains. 
 
 Such low prices as these do not apply to Athens after the 
 Persian war. In the time of Solon, indeed, an ox cost only five 
 drachmas, a sheep one drachma, and a medimnus of corn the 
 same sum ; but prices gradually rose to five times, in many 
 things to as much as ten or twenty times their former amount, 
 which after the examples of more recent times, is not surprising. 
 The quantity of money in use was not only increased, but through 
 a rising population and an extended intercourse its circulation 
 was accelerated. Thus Athens, as early as in the age of Socra- 
 tes, was considered an expensive place of residence^^*. 
 
 Upon the whole, the cheapness of commodities in ancient 
 times has been exaggerated by some writers, who thought that 
 the nearest approach would be made to the truth by assuming 
 that prices were on an average ten times lower than in the 
 eighteenth century"^; whereas the prices of com, by which many 
 other prices are necessarily regulated, prove the contrary. But 
 that the reader may be enabled to form a more determinate 
 judgment upon this subject, I will explicitly treat in succession 
 of the prices of land, of slaves, of cattle, corn, bread, wine, oil, 
 and other necessaries of life, and also of wood, clothing, and the 
 different sorts of implements and furniture, as far as I have 
 been able to find information upon these points. 
 
 ^^° xxxiv. 8, 7. Concerning the 
 reading see Schweighaeuser in the 
 Lexicon Polyb. p. 555. 
 
 ^*' See above, chap. iv. 
 
 ""= Plutarch, de Anim. Tranquil. 10. 
 
 ^^3 Gillies ut sup. p. 19. Wolf 
 makes the same supposition in his 
 Essay : Ueber sine milde Stiftimg 
 Trajans, p. 6.
 
 62 PRICES OF LAND [bK, I. 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 Prices of Land and Mines in Attica. 
 
 The value of the cultivated land in Attica was naturally very 
 different according to its situation and goodness. The estates 
 in the vicinit}" of the city bore a much higher price than 
 those at a distance^^* ; the wooded land (7^ 7re(f)VT€v/jL6V7]) must 
 have been dearer than the bare or unplanted land {yrj ^jrcXr}), 
 the rich and good than the poor soils. Among the many 
 passages upon the value of land, one alone contains an approxi- 
 mate statement of the area, and this without any particulars as 
 to situation and quality. Aristophanes, according to the state- 
 ment of Lysias*", had bought a house for fifty minas and also 
 300 plethra of land; both together cost him more than five 
 talents. If we assume that it cost him five talents and twenty 
 minas, and subtract from this sum the value of the house, there 
 remain for the land 27^000 drachmas, which gives ninety 
 drachmas for one plethron. Now the plethron was equal to 
 10,000 feet of Greek square measure, 9620 Rhenish, or 9900 
 English feet, according to Ideler^s researches. The English 
 acre of 43,5 GO square feet would thus have cost 396 drachmas ; 
 which does not by any means agree with the exaggerated notion 
 above alluded to, that prices were ten times lower in ancient 
 than in modern times. It is however by no means improbable 
 that much land bore a lower value ; but fifty drachmas may be 
 fairly assumed as the average price of the plethron, without 
 taking into consideration accidental circumstances by which the 
 value of the land might be lowered. 
 
 It should also be mentioned that in Attica the land was 
 probably divided into portions of no very great extent. Alci- 
 biades' paternal inheritance did not amount to more than the 
 estate purchased by Aristophanes, although his was one of the 
 
 254 Y^ 
 
 253 
 
 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. j that Aristoiihanes is stated to have 
 
 Orat. pro Aristoph. bonis p. 633 purchased not 300 plethra, but more 
 and p. 642, wliere for ovalav read with ! than 300 plethra: y^y TrXfovrJTpiaKoaia 
 Alarkland oIkuiv. [It is to be observed nXeOpa. ^^ 31, ed. Bekker.— Than sl.]
 
 r-H. XI.] 
 
 AND MINES IN ATTICA. 
 
 63 
 
 most distinguished families. It was not until the time of 
 Demosthenes that individuals purchased much land. The most 
 extensive possessions were those which commonly went by the 
 name of boundary estates {io-xctTtat), which were situated at a 
 distance either upon the sea-shore or at the foot of the moun- 
 tains*'^ Thus the boundary estate of Timarchus in Sphettus is 
 stated to have been extensive, but it had run wild through 
 his neglect^"'. The estate belonging to Phsenippus in Cytheron 
 contained more than forty stadia, or 1440 plethra"^ 
 
 Of other estates I have noted down the following prices. 
 An estate situated in Sphettus is mentioned in Lysias as 
 being worth five minas ; another occurs in Isseus worth above 
 ten minas, and in the former orator an estate in Cicynna is 
 estimated by the creditor at ten minas*^^ In like manner 
 in Terence^®", an estate is stated to be mortgaged for the 
 latter sum. Timarchus sold an estate in Alopecse, distant 
 eleven or twelve stadia from the walls, under its value for twenty 
 minas''^ Again, an estate is mentioned in Prospalta, which 
 was hardly worth thirty minas^^% and one in CEnoe for fifty 
 minas"^ An estate of Ciron^s was, according to the expression 
 of Isseus, well worth a talent : whence we may conclude that an 
 estate no larger than this was thought a considerable possession; 
 an estate of the same value occurs in Demosthenes, which 
 appears to have contained vineyards^^^ The following sums 
 are still more considerable, viz.: seventy minas, and seventy-five 
 minas for an estate in Athmonon, two talents for a property in 
 Eleusis, and two and half talents for the same in Thria^". 
 
 ■''^ Harpoc. in v. (axaria, Schol. ad. 
 ^schin. cont. Timarch. p. 736, 737> 
 ed Reisk. Lex. Seg. p. 256, and the 
 Commentators upon iEschines and 
 Demosthenes in the passages to be 
 quoted. Herodotus also (vi. 127) calls 
 distant estates eVxartat. The supposi- 
 tion that the estates on the boundaries 
 of the boroughs were so called is un- 
 doubtedly false, unless indeed boroughs, 
 as was the case with many, were 
 bounded by the sea and by mountains. 
 
 ^^' ^schin. cont. Timarch. p. 117, 
 119. 
 
 253 Orat. cont. Phc-enipp. p. 1040, 15. 
 
 ^^^ Lysias nepl b-qfxoa. ddiK. p. 594, 
 cf. p. 593, 595, Isffius de Menecl. 
 Hered. p. 221, ed. OreU. 
 
 '^0 Phorm. iv. 3, 56. 
 
 '^^1 yEsch. cont. Timarch. p. 119. 
 
 2^^ Isseus de Ilagn. Hered. p. 298. 
 
 263 Is. ut sup. p. 294. 
 
 2^^ Is. de Ciron. Hered. p. 218. 
 Demosth. cont. Onet. i. p. 872, ad fin. 
 ii. p. 876, 10, cf. i. p. 871, 22. 
 
 '"^^ Isseus de Menecl. Hered. p. 220, 
 221, ed. Orcll. de Philectem. Hered. 
 p. 140, de Ilagn, Ilcred. p. 292 sqq.
 
 64 
 
 PRICES OF HOUSES IX ATTICA. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 Concerning other kinds of landed property I have been 
 unable to obtain any information, except that mine-shares were 
 sold for a talent and ninety minas, although their price may at 
 times have been enhanced by particular circumstance^''^ 
 
 Chapter XII. 
 Prices of Houses in Attica. 
 
 With regard to houses, we know that Athens contained above 
 10,000"^; which probably does not include the public edifices 
 and the buildings without the walls ; the city and the harbours 
 being nearly 200 stadia in circumference, there were many 
 places 'v\ithin so large an area upon which no buildings were 
 erected*®^. The houses were for the most part small and mean 
 in appearance, the streets crooked and narrow ; " a stranger/' 
 says Dicsearchus, ^^ might doubt upon a sudden view whether 
 this were really the city of Athens/' the Piraeus alone had 
 been laid out according to rule, in the time of Themistocles, by 
 the architect Hippodamus^°^ The upper stories often projected 
 over the streets; staircases, balustrades, and doors opening 
 outwards, obstructed and narrowed the way. Themistocles and 
 Aristides, with the entire cooperation)of the Areopagus, gained 
 nothing more by their endeavours than that a stop was put to 
 any farther narrowing of the streets by building, a measure 
 which was adhered to in later times^^°. The plan of Hippias 
 and Iphicrates for breaking down everything that projected into 
 the public streets*^' w^as not carried into execution, because 
 tiieir object was not the embellishment of the city, but to obtain 
 money by fraudulent means. 
 
 With the exception of the magnificent public edifices, they 
 did not begin to build good houses until the time of Demos- 
 
 *^^ See my Dissertation upon the 
 Silver Mines of Lanrion, in vol. ii. 
 
 ^^' Xenopli. ;Mem. Socrat. iii. 6, 14. 
 To tliis Xenoph. CEcon. 8. 22, is also 
 referred ; but not with any certainty. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. de Vectio;. 2. 
 
 *^^ Dicaarchus p. 8, and Aristot. 
 Polit. vi. 2, vii. II, and the Commen- 
 tators. 
 
 ^70 Heraclid. Pont, and Xenopli. de 
 Rep. Ath. 3. 
 
 ■'''' See Meursius F. A. p. 20.
 
 CH. XII.] PRICES OF HOUSES IN ATTICA. 65 
 
 thenes. "Formerly/^ says this orator"^*, "the republic had 
 abundant wealth, but no individual raised himself above 
 the multitude. If any one of us could now see the houses 
 of Themistocles, Aristides, Miltiades, Cimon, or the famous 
 men of those days, he would perceive that they were not 
 more magnificent than the houses of ordinary persons ; while 
 the buildings of the state are of such number and magni- 
 tude that they cannot be surpassed ;^^ and afterwards he com- 
 plains that the statesmen of his time constructed houses which 
 exceeded the public buildings in magnificence. Meidias built a 
 house in Eleusis larger than any in that place*^^. The greater 
 number of houses were however even at this time badly built, 
 as Photion^s^'% for example ; and, like those of Pompeii and Her- 
 culaneum, they occupied only a limited space, for which reason 
 their price could not have been high. Labour was cheap, there 
 was stone in plenty, and wood could be easily brought to the 
 place of building ; and another circumstance which diminished 
 the price of houses was, that they were for the most part either 
 built with a frame-work, or of unburnt bricks dried in the open 
 air, which latter mode of building, as being more durable than 
 with soft stones, was sometimes even employed in splendid and 
 costly edifices*'\ An advantageous situation and the customary 
 high rate of house rent, might however raise the value of houses. 
 It was also of course possible for large sums of money to be 
 expended by foolish and extravagant speculations upon an 
 useless house*'^. It should be observed that the Attic idiom 
 distinguishes between dwelling-houses (ot/c/at), and lodging- 
 houses (crvvoiKlat); accidentally indeed a dwelling-house might 
 be let out for lodgings, and a lodging-house have been inhabited 
 by the proprietor himself; which will explain how learned writers 
 could fall into the error of supposing that the latter word 
 
 ^''^ Demosth. cont. Aristocrat, p. 
 C89 11—24, Olynth. iii. p. 35, 14—24, 
 p. 3G, 20, from both of which the pas- 
 sage in the Oration nepl avvrd^fcoi, p. 
 174-5, is made up. For the whole 
 speech has been correctly abjudged 
 from Demosthenes. 
 
 '7^ Demosth. c. Mid. p. 565, 24. 
 
 27^ Plut. Phoc. 18. 
 
 ^^^ That the private buildings of the 
 Athenians were constructed of bricks 
 of unburnt clay is in part proved by 
 Demosthenes ap. Plutarch, in Vit. 
 Demosth. 11. For the rest see Hirt, 
 Baukunst der Alten, p. 143. 
 
 '^''' Xenoph. CEcon. 3, 1. 
 F
 
 66 
 
 PRICES OF HOUSES IN ATTICA. 
 
 [bk. 1. 
 
 {(TvvoiKia), frequently means a house in general without any 
 addition of the idea of letting ; whereas the derivation of the 
 word plainly shews that it denotes a dwelling together of several 
 families^ of whom either some or all are lodgers. 
 
 The prices of houses, which are mentioned in the ancient 
 ■writers, vary from 3 minas to 120, according to their size, 
 situation, and condition. The data are as follows: a small 
 house estimated by Isjeus at less than 3 minas, though he 
 probably depreciates its value ; a house at Eleusis worth 5 
 minas, mentioned by the same orator^^^; a very small house 
 near the temple of Hermes Psithyristes at Athens, sold for 
 7 minas, according to another orator*^^ ; another house which 
 was pledged for 10 minas, according to Demosthenes, a 
 possession belonging to poor people, as is evident from their 
 inconsiderable dowry of 40 minas, and from other circum- 
 stances*'^ ; to these may be added a house noticed in Terence 
 which is mortgaged for the same sum, a poet who generally 
 represents the usages and customs of Athens*®" ; a dwelling- 
 house in the city, worth 13 minas, mentioned by Isseus^^' ; a 
 lodging-house in the country mortgaged for 16 minas, in De- 
 mosthenes**'' ; a house in the city that had been let, worth 20 
 minas, in Isseus*^ ; and several houses of the same value in 
 Demosthenes and ^schines*"*, one of them behind the Acro- 
 polis ; a house sold for 30 minas, and another of the same 
 value in Isaeus and Demosthenes'^^ the former in Melitej a 
 lodging-house in the Cerameicus, worth 40 minas, given as a 
 dowry, in Isseus ; another in the city transferred for the sum 
 of 44 minas, in the same orator^^^ ; likewise one for 50 minas 
 in Isseus and Lysias^"; a lodging-house belonging to the 
 rich merchant Pasion, valued at 100 minas*^^; and, lastly. 
 
 ^" Is?Gus de Mcnecl. Ilered. p. 221, 
 ed. Orell. de Hagn. Ilered. p. 293. 
 
 278 Orat. cont. Neaor. p. 1358, 6—9. 
 
 '^'^ Demosth. cont. Spud. p. 1029, 
 20, cf. p. 1032, 21, p. 1033, 28. 
 
 ^^f* Phorm.iv. 3, 58. 
 
 2^' De Ciron. Hered. p. 210. 
 
 •^82 Cont. Nicosti-at. p. 1250, 18. 
 
 '8^ Utsiip. 
 
 ■"^' Demosth. c. Onetor. ii. p. 8/0,9, 
 and passim ; ^Esch. c. Timarch. p. 119. 
 
 ^^ Isa3us de Hagn. Hered. p. 293 ; 
 Demosth. c. Aphob. i. p. 816, 21. 
 
 ^« Do Dicreog. Hered. p. 104 ; de 
 Philoctem. Ilered. p. 140. 
 
 ^7 Is. do Dicieog. Ilered. p. 105 ; 
 Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 633. 
 
 ■'*° Demosth. c. Stephan. i. p. 1110,8.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 PRICES OF SLAVES. 
 
 67 
 
 in Plautus a house purchased, with comic liberality, for 2 
 talents, having two wooden columns connected with it, valued, 
 exclusively of the cost of the carriage, at 3 minas^^^ To these 
 may be added 30 minas, the value of a bathing house at 
 Serangium in the Pirceus"" ; and another of which the value 
 may be fairly estimated at 40 minas, as the person, who was 
 cast in a law-suit on the occasion, was compelled to pay that 
 sum for it^^'. 
 
 Chapter XIII. 
 
 Prices of Slaves. 
 
 The market-price of slaves, exclusively of the variations 
 caused by the greater or less demand and supply *^% v as very 
 different according to their age, health, strength, beauty, natural 
 abilities, mechanical ingenuity, and moral qualities. Some 
 slaves, says Xenophon"% are well worth 2 minas, others 
 hardly half a mina; many sold for 5 or 10 minas, and 
 Nicias the son of Niceratus is stated to have given no less 
 than a talent for an overseer of the mines. The slaves em- 
 ployed in the mills and mines were undoubtedly the lowest. 
 Lucian, in the ludicrous valuation of the philosophers^^*, 
 estimates Socrates at 2 talents, a Peripatetic at 20, Chry- 
 sippus at 12, a Pythagorean at 10, and Dion of Syracuse at 
 2 minas, and, to omit the value of Diogenes, reckons Philon 
 the Sceptic at a mina, remarking at the same time that he was 
 destined for the mill ; the latter therefore is evidently the 
 price of a slave employed in the mills. ^^ Assuming,^^ observes 
 Xenophon, "that the Athenian state^" purchases 1200 slaves, 
 and lets them out on hire into the mines for a daily payment of 
 one obolus a head, and that the whole revenue accruing from this 
 source is annually applied to the purchase of fresh slaves, who 
 
 ^» Mostell. iii. 1, 113 sqq. ; iii. 2, 
 138. I omit other passages which do 
 not refer to Athens, such as that in 
 the spurious Epistle of ^schines, 0. 
 
 ■■"^'^ Is. de Philoct. Hered. p. 140 
 Compare also Harpocration in v. 
 Sr/pdyytoj/. 
 
 ^^^ Isscus de Dicaeog. Tiered, p. 101. 
 
 ^- Such for example as those paid 
 for the Carthaginian soldiers, according 
 to Liv. xxi. 41. 
 
 ^^^ Mem. Socrat. ii. 3, 2. 
 
 -^' Bicov Trpdais, 27. 
 
 •29 5 j)q Vectig. 4, 23. 
 
 F 2
 
 68 PRICES OF SLAVES. [bK. I. 
 
 should again be let out at a like profit, which receipts should 
 be applied as before, and so on for ever, the state would, by 
 means of these successive returns, have 6000 slaves in five or 
 six years." If, as I believe, the original 1200 are compre- 
 hended in this number, the price is here taken at from 125 to 
 150 drachmas ; if they are not comprised in the estimate, 
 which appears to me improbable, a slave in the mines would 
 be only reckoned at from 100 to 125 drachmas. According to 
 the account of Demosthenes"^ 105 minas were lent upon the 
 security of a mine, and 30 slaves employed in working it ; this 
 was arranged by a fictitious purchase made by two creditors, 
 one of whom, Nicobulus, gave 45 minas, the other, Euergus, a 
 talent ; the latter held the mine, the former the slaves, as a 
 pledge, which they were to cede as soon as the contract of 
 purchase ceased to be in force"^ ; consequently each slave was 
 in this case estimated at 150 drachmas : nor could a slave of 
 this description in general have been worth more, although the 
 antagonists of Demosthenes' client maintained that the mines 
 and slaves together were worth a much larger sum*^^. The 
 statement of Barthelemy^®% who supposes that the value of 
 the mine-slaves varied from 300 to 600 drachmas, rests upon 
 an erroneous assumption. 
 
 Ordinary house-slaves, both male and female, could not have 
 been worth much more than those just mentioned^"". The valua- 
 tion of two slaves, each at 2i minas, is considered by Demos- 
 thene3^°^ as high ; in the same author we read of a slave who 
 was sold for 2 minas^"^ Demosthenes' father was possessed of 
 
 25« Cont. Pantsenet. p. 967. 
 
 2S7 See p. 967, 18, and p. 972, 21. 
 
 ^^ See my Dissertation on the Sil- 
 ver Mines of Laurion, in vol. ii. 
 
 '^^ Anachars. torn. v. p. 35. 
 
 ^o** Upon this point compare the 
 vague statements in Aristoph. Pint. 
 147 ; Isscus de Ciron. Hered. p. 218 — 
 
 highjbecause from the words to fxeyedos 
 T^s d7roypa(f)rjs he assumed a high valu- 
 ation ; and tliat therefore the words of 
 the orator must be interpreted as if 
 each of the two slaves was estimated 
 at that sum ; but that since fx^yedos 
 might also be understood of a less 
 amount, and as tlie context, although 
 
 220. I very obscure, seems to require this 
 
 20' Cont. Nicest, p. 1246, 7- The meaning, it might be preferable to 
 author afterwards states in the Ad- suppose that the two slaves were toge- 
 denda, that " he had considered the ther valued at 2^ minas.'* 
 estimate of two slaves at 2^ minas as j *^'^ Cont. Spud. p. 1030, 8.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 PRICES OP SLAVES, 
 
 69 
 
 workers of iron or sword-cutlers, some of whom were worth 5, 
 some 6, and the lowest more than 3 mmas, and 20 chair-makers 
 together worth 40 minas. The chair-makers with the 32 or 33 
 sword-makers, including a capital of a talent, are stated at 4 
 talents 50 minas^"^. But when in another place the same orator 
 reckons 14 sword-cutlers (although they might have been of 
 advanced age), together with 30 minas, at only 70 minas^"*, 
 and consequently each at ?! drachmas, he is manifestly guilty 
 of an intentional falsehood. How great an influence a know- 
 ledge of any art had upon the value of the slave is shown by 
 this example of the sword-cutlers ; for the higher profit they 
 afforded the greater was their value. While a slave in the 
 mines only yielded a profit of an obolus a day, a worker in 
 leather produced two, and the master of the workshop three 
 oboli^"; from whence it can be judged how large may have 
 been the profit which the manufacturers of fine ornamental 
 goods, such as head-nets (aaKxv(j>avTac), or of stuffs of Amorgus 
 and variegated cloths [iroLKiXTol), yielded to their possessors^"*. 
 Five minas, which we found above to have been given for slaves 
 skilled in some art, appear moreover not to have been at all 
 uncommon^**^, as is shown by an account in Diogenes^"^. The 
 Roman soldiers whom Hannibal had sold in Achaia, were 
 
 303 Demosth. c. Aphob. i. p. 816, 5. 
 
 »"* Cf. Demosth. c. Aphob. p. 815, 
 p. 817, 23, and p. 821. 
 
 ''"* ^schin. cont. Timarch. p. 118. 
 
 30^ Concerning the (raKxv(f)dvTai see 
 Demosth. cont. Olympiod. p. 1170, 27; 
 Pollux X. 192. The interpretation 
 given in Lex Seg. p. 302, is incorrect- 
 For the other points cf. ^sch. ut sup. 
 Concerning the ttolkiKttjs, afterwards 
 called nXovfidpins {plumarius, see INIu- 
 ratori Inscript. vol. ii. p. 906, 13, and 
 again p. 924, 11, together with his 
 Dissertation de Textrina in the Ant. 
 Ital.) ; Pollux vii. 34, 35, and the 
 commentators, Schol. ^sch. p. 730, 
 ed. Reiske, and Lex Seg. p. 295. 
 
 ^"^ It might also be supposed that 
 the price of 5 minas for slaves at the 
 oars (kwttcis) was mentioned in Ando- 
 
 cides de suo Reditu, p. 81, if in that 
 passage we write TreVre fj.v(ov for TrevTf 
 bpaxfi^v : for what Reiske (Ind. An- 
 doc. Orat. Att. torn. viii. p. 503), in- 
 fers from this passage, Remigis erat 
 ingens pretium quinque drachmcBj will 
 not mislead any reader. KwTreuy, 
 however, does not mean a rower, but 
 a piece of wood for an oar, as may be 
 easily seen by a comparison of the 
 passages, where it was supposed to 
 mean a rower. Of these is the pas- 
 sage in Andocides, where the context 
 clearly shows, that pieces of wood for 
 oars, and not slaves for the oars, are 
 intended : and a piece of wood of this 
 description was probably well paid for 
 at 5 drachmas. 
 
 ^"^^ Vol. ii. in the Life of Aristippus.
 
 70 
 
 PRICES OF SLAVES. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 ransomed at a compensation of 5 minas each, the price having 
 been fixed by the Acheeans themselves, and the state paid it to 
 their respective possessors'"'. These statements agree for the 
 most part with the prices which were paid for some slaves sold 
 to the Delphian Apollo, upon the condition that the individuals 
 who thus became sacred property should in all other respects 
 be free, and ever after be exempt from serving any person 
 as slaves. In instruments of sale belonging to this kind of 
 transfer we find 4 minas paid for a male, from 3 to 5 for a 
 female^ ^° ; yet in a sale which took place at Amphissa to the 
 temple of Apollo not less than 1000 drachmas are given for 
 a male slave. Plautus appears, as is frequently the case with 
 the comic poets, to make a high estimate, w^hen he values 
 a strong useful slave at 20 minas, and supposes a child 
 to be sold for 6 minas'^'. The father of Theocrines was 
 condemned to pay to the state a fine of 500 drachmas for 
 having attempted to emancipate a female slave of Cephiso- 
 dorus. The sum paid to the state for an offence of this 
 nature w^as, according to law, the half of the complete fine, 
 the other half went to the injured master ; and it is probable 
 that this was a simple compensation for the loss sustained, 
 so that the female slave appears to have been valued at 5 
 minas ^^^ For women who prostituted their persons, and female 
 players on the cithara, 20 or 30 minas occur as common 
 prices ^'^ Neeera was sold for 30 minas '^*. A negro-woman 
 and an old eunuch are sold in a play of Terence for 20 
 
 ^"^ 1200 cost the state a hundred 
 talents according to Polybius, liv. 
 xxxiv. 50. This was in Olymp. 14G, 
 1, A. u. c. 558 (196 B.C.) 
 
 ^'** See Corp. Inscript. Gra>c. Nos. 
 1607, 1608, 1690—1710. The sacred 
 slaves, lepodovXoi, were of this descrip- 
 tion, as e. g. the Venerii at Eryx in 
 Sicily, the female servants of Aphro- 
 dite at Corinth, the Hieroduli of Co- 
 mana upon the Pontus, which the 
 priests could no more sell to another 
 person, than the Thessalians could sell 
 
 their bondsmen the Penesta?, or the 
 Spartans their Helots, out of the 
 country. Cf. Strab. xii. p. 384. 
 
 2" Captiv. ii. 2, 103, v. 2, 21, 4, 15. 
 
 ^'2 Orat. cont. Theocriu. p. 1327, 
 1328, see book iii. ch. 12. 
 
 313 Terent. Adelph. ii. 1, 37, 2, 15, 
 iv. 7, 24, and elsewhere, Plant. Mos- 
 tellar. in several places, Curcul. i. 1, 
 63, ii. 3,65, and passim, Terent. Phorm. 
 iii. 3, 24, Isocrat. nepl uvridoa-ccos, 
 p. 12i, ed. OreU. 
 
 3'^ Orat. cont. Neocr. p. 1354, IC.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 PRICES OF SLAVES. 
 
 71 
 
 minas^'^ Even these priceswere still further enhanced by luxury; 
 and although at Athens an excellent slave could be bought for 10 
 minas, the price at Rome in the time of Columella exceeded 
 even this amount^'% in the same manner that the value of 
 negro-slaves has at the present day considerably increased: 
 as early as in the age of the first Ptolemies, an Alexandrian 
 talent was the price given for the males and females who 
 attended at court^'^. 
 
 The ransom-money for captives was only in part regulated 
 by the price of slaves. This may be seen from the fact that 
 the Chalcideans, who before the Persian war remained pri- 
 soners in Athens, were ransomed at 2 minas a head^^^; at 
 which sum subsequently the indigent citizens of Potideea 
 were valued, and paid taxes for it as for property of the 
 same amount. Again, Dionysius the elder, after he had con- 
 quered the Rhegini, first compelled them to make good the 
 expenses of the war, and then demanded for each man a ran- 
 som of 3 minas, or, according to Diodorus, 1 mina^'^; Han- 
 nibal also agreed to ransom the Roman prisoners at 3 minas 
 a head; and finally, in the time of Philip, when there were 
 many Athenian prisoners in Macedonia, the customary ransom 
 varied from 3 to 5 minas ^^^ But since it frequently hap- 
 pened that not only the respectabihty and character of a man, 
 but also his wealth and importance, were taken into considera- 
 tion, a higher rate of ransom was in such cases arbitrarily fixed. 
 Nicostratus, as appears in a speech attributed to Demosthenes^*', 
 ransomed himself for 26 minas; Plato was freed from captivity 
 by Anniceris for 20 or 30 minas; with which sum, the friends 
 of the philosopher having raised the money for the ransom and 
 
 215 Terent. Eunuch, i. 2, 89. In v. 
 5, 13, he inaccurately says that the 
 eunuch cost the same sum. The ne- 
 gress appears to have been worth but 
 little, cf. iii. 2, 18. 
 
 2'® Hamberger De pretiis rerum, 
 p. 32. Cf. Jugler de Nundin. Serv. 7, 
 p. 85 sqq. 
 
 '"^^^ Joseph. Antiq. Jud. xii. 4. 
 
 ^1" Herod, v. 77- 
 
 t ^-^ The former according to the se- 
 cond book of the (Economics attributed 
 to Aristotle, from -nhich the account 
 of Diodorus xiv. ill, disagi'ees in se- 
 veral points. The date of this occur- 
 rence is Olymp. 98, 2 (b.c. 387). 
 
 ^"^« Polyb. vi. 56, Demosth. de fals. 
 leg. p. 394, 13. 
 
 ^^^' Cont. Nicostrat. p. 1248, 23.
 
 72 
 
 PRICES OF SLAVES. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 given it to Anniceris, the latter purchased him a garden adjoin- 
 ing the Academy^". Philip affirms in his Epistle to the Athe- 
 nians^" that the Attic general Diopeithes had refused to ransom 
 Amphilochus, a man of consideration who was employed upon 
 embassies^ for less than 15 talents. Hence in order to prevent 
 any arbitrary proceedings, Demetrius Poliorcetes concluded an 
 agreement with the Rhodians that the free inhabitants should 
 be ransomed for 10 and the slaves for 5 minas^^*. 
 
 The rights of property with regard to slaves in no way dif- 
 fered from any other chattel; they could be given or taken as 
 pledges^". They laboured either on their master's account or 
 their own, in consideration of a certain sum tob e paid to the 
 master, or they were let out on hire either for the mines, or any 
 other kinds of labour, and even for other persons' workshops, 
 or as hired servants for wages {airocpopaj^^^: a similar payment 
 was also exacted by the masters from their slaves serving in the 
 fleet. The profit derived from the slaves was necessarily 
 very great; for the owner must have replaced his outlay of 
 capital and ensured the usual high rate of interest, exactly in 
 the same manner as if it had been vested in cattle, since the 
 value of slaves was destroyed by age, and at their death the 
 money vested in them was lost. To this must be added the 
 great danger of their elopement, especially when there was war 
 in the country, and they were with the armies ^*^; it then 
 became necessar}^ to pursue them, and offer rewards publicly 
 for their recapture {acoarpa) ^^^. The idea of an institution for 
 the insurance of slaves first occurred to a Macedonian grandee, 
 Antigenes of Rhodes, who undertook, for a yearly contribution 
 of 8 drachmas for each slave that was in the army, to make 
 
 '^* Diog. Laert. iii. 21, Plutarch, de 
 Exilio 10, Seneca Epist. 74, iSIacrob. 
 Sat. i. 11. The account of Diodorus 
 XV. 7, is, as usual, confused. 
 
 3« Demosth. p. 159, 15. 
 
 ^" Diod. XX. 84. 
 
 ="^5 Demosth. c. Pantaenet. p. 967, c. 
 Aphob. p. 821, 12, p. 822, c. Onetor. i. 
 p. 871, 11. 
 
 •^" Demosth. c. Nicostrat. p. 1253, 
 
 1, 11, c. Aphob. 1. p. 819, 2G, Xenopli. 
 de Rep. Ath. 1, in several places, par- 
 ticularly in chap. 11, which passage 
 (as corrected by Heindorf) appears 
 chiefly to refer to the pay of the sailors ; 
 Theoph. Char. 22, Andoc. de Myst. 
 p. 19. 
 
 327 Thucyd. vii. 13 and 27. 
 
 3^^ Plat. Protag. init. Xenoph. Mem. 
 Socr. ii. 10, 2.
 
 CH. Xlll.] 
 
 PRICES OF SLAVES. 
 
 7a 
 
 good his price, as estimated by the owner at the time of elope- 
 ment; which he was easily able to do, by compelling the governors 
 either to return the slaves who had fled into their provinces, or 
 to pay for them^^^. It cannot however be determined with any 
 accuracy how high was the rate of profit which a slave returned. 
 The thirty-two or thirty-three iron-workers or sword-cutlers 
 belonging to Demosthenes, annually produced a net profit of 
 30, and the twenty chair-makers of 12 minas ; the value of the 
 former being 190, of the latter 40 minas ^^"; the latter produced 
 30, the former only 15^f per cent., a disparity sufficiently 
 remarkable. It is however to be mentioned, that the master 
 furnished the raw materials for manufacturing, and perhaps we 
 ought to consider what he gained upon the raw materials as 
 constituting a part of the whole profit. The leather-workers 
 of Timarchus produced to their master 2, the overseer 3 oboli 
 a day, but probably this return is not to be considered as 
 arising only from the capital vested in the slaves, as it must 
 have also included the profit which the master derived from the 
 supply of the raw materials. Hence it may be concluded that 
 when mine-slaves let out to a tenant yielded to their master a 
 profit of an obolus a day, which, reckoning 350 working days 
 and an average value of 140 drachmas, gives 47i-f per cent., the 
 rent thus paid extended not only to the slaves, but also to the 
 mines let out with them ; an inference which I have supported 
 with other arguments elsewhere ^^^ 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 
 Prices of Horses, Cattle, Sheep, and other animals. 
 
 Among domestic animals, horses were in Attica sold for com- 
 paratively high prices, not only on account of their utility and 
 the difficulty of keeping them, but from the disposition of the 
 Athenians to extravagance and display: while the knights kept 
 
 3^» See Pseud- Arist. (Econ. ii. 2, 34. 
 Antigenes for Antimenes is an emend- 
 ation of Niebuhr. [Concerning this 
 emendation, see some remarks in the 
 
 Philol. Mus. vol. i. p. 139.— Transl.] 
 ^3« Demosth. cont. Aphob. i. p. 816. 
 33^ Dissertation on the Mines of 
 
 Laurion, in vol. ii.
 
 74 
 
 PRICES OF HORSES^ CATTLE, ETC. 
 
 [bk, 
 
 expensive horses for military service and processions at the 
 festivals, and while men of ambition and high rank trained 
 them for the games and races, there arose, particularly among 
 the young men, that excessive passion for horses, of which 
 Aristophanes gives an example in the Clouds, and which is 
 recorded by several ancient writers ^^' ; so that many were 
 impoverished by keeping horses, although it is true that others 
 were enriched by the same means ^^^ In early times also tech- 
 nical principles had been laid down concerning the management 
 of horses, and rules of this kind had been published before the 
 time of Xenophon by Simon a celebrated rider^^^. The price of 
 a common horse, such as a countryman used, was 3 minas. 
 '' You have not squandered your property,^^ says the client of 
 Isseus^^^, by keeping horses, "for never were you in posses- 
 sion of a horse which was worth more than 3 minas/^ But 
 a good saddle-horse, or a horse for running in chariot-races, 
 according to Aristophanes, cost 12 minas ; and since this sum 
 is lent upon a horse in pawn, it must have been a common 
 price ^^^. But fashion or fancy for horses raised their price 
 beyond all limits. Thus 13 talents were given for Buce- 
 phalus ^^^ A yoke of mules, probably two animals, and not 
 particularly good ones, but only destined for the ordinary pur- 
 poses of country work, were sold for 5 and a half and also 
 for 8 minas ^^^ Asses were probably much cheaper in pro- 
 portion; yet besides the ludicrous story of Lucian^^^ that the 
 ass Lucius, when no purchaser could be found for him, was at 
 last disposed of to an itinerant priest of the Syrian goddess for 
 the sum of 30 drachmas, I have been unable to meet with any- 
 thing upon this point in reference to Greece, and even this 
 passage proves nothing with respect to the usual price in 
 ancient times, and particularly in Attica, 
 
 ^^^ Cf. Xenop. de re Equestri, i. 12. 
 Tereut. Andr. i. 1. Bach ad Xenopli. 
 CEcon. 2, «, &c. 
 
 3^=» Xenoph. (Econ. 3, 8. Many an- 
 cient writers speak of KadLTrnoTpocfieTv. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. de re Equestri, c. 1, 
 and see Sclmeider's note. 
 
 3^5 De DicEoog. Hered. p. 116. 
 33" Aristoph. Nub. 20, 1226. Lysias 
 Karrj-y. kukoX, p. 306 sq. 
 3^7 Chai-es ap. Gell. Noct. Att. v. 2. 
 ^3« Isaius de Philoct. Ilcred. p. 140. 
 3^^ Asiu. 35.
 
 CII. XIV.] PRICES OF HORSES^ CATTLE, ETC. 
 
 75 
 
 With regard to the prices of cattle, I am at a loss to guess 
 whence an English writer could have derived the statement that 
 an ox in the time of Socrates cost 8 shillings; an assertion which is 
 contradicted by the concurrent testimony of all writers who men- 
 tion the subject. If indeed 2 drachmas were paid for an ox at 
 the Delian Theoria^", I vAW not deny that in the most ancient 
 times this price may have existed ; but of later times it is 
 inconceivable, and the most that can be allowed is, that in the 
 distribution of the prizes, which were merely a matter of honour, 
 this primitive standard may have been retained. In Athens, 
 at the time of Solon, an ox, probably one selected as a victim, 
 was sold for 5 drachmas, five times as much as a sheep^"'; in 
 Lusitania, according to Polybius, for 10 drachmas, and a sheep 
 in like manner a fifth of this sum ; in Rome the price of an ox 
 was ten times that of a sheep^^*. If, therefore, in the flourish- 
 ing times of Athens, a sheep, as will be presently shown, cost 
 from 10 to 20 drachmas, according to its age, breed, and 
 the variation in the market-price, an ox may be reckoned at 
 from 50 to 100 drachmas. In Olymp. 92. 3 (b.c. 410) 5114 
 drachmas were paid for a hecatomb, and if we suppose that 
 nearly 100 oxen were purchased for it, the price of an ox 
 amounted to about 51 drachmas. But in Olymp. 101. 3. 
 (b.c. 3/9) a hecatomb of 109 oxen cost 8419 drachmas, that is 
 771 drachmas a head ; in both cases oxen selected for victims 
 are meant^*^. 
 
 Probably also in other countries except Athens, prices 
 were not much lower at this period; in Sicily, which 
 abounded with cattle, in the time of Epicharmus the price was 
 the same as at Athens in the days of Solon. For a fine calf, 
 according to that comic poet, was sold for 10 nummi^'''', or 2 
 drachmas 4f oboli of Attic money^^^; and since it may be 
 
 3^° Pollux ix. 61, where the Com- 
 mentators question the fact. 
 
 3-»i Plutarch. Solon. 23, from Deme- 
 trius Phalereus. 
 
 ^*'^ Hamberger in the Treatise 
 above quoted. Taylor ad Marm. 
 Sandw. p. 37. 
 
 ^*^ See the second Prytaneia of the 
 
 Choiseul Inscnption, and Barthe'Iemy 
 in the Mem. de I'Acad. des Inscrip- 
 tions, vol. xlviii. p. 355, also Corp. 
 Inscript. No. 158 ; cf. Taylor ad Mann, 
 Sandw. p. 30. 
 
 ^^^ Ap. Poll. Lx. 80; 
 
 ^^* According t4) the assumption in 
 chap. 4.
 
 76 
 
 PRICES OF HORSES, CATTLE, ETC. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 inferred, from the analogy of the prices in Lusitania, that the 
 value of a full-grown ox was double, it is probable that at 
 that time in Sicily, an ox of similar quality might have sold 
 for 20 nummi, or 5 drachmas 3^ oboli of Attic money. A 
 sucking pig was sold at Athens, in the Peloponnesian war, for 
 3 drachmas^*^ A small sheep for a sacrifice, picked out 
 for the use of the temple, is estimated in Menander at 10 
 drachmas^*^ In the time of Lysias, the prices cannot have 
 been at all lower ; for otherwise the dishonest guardian men- 
 tioned in this orator could not have set down 16 drachmas 
 for a lamb at the Dionysia, whatever might have been his 
 eagerness to overrate the charges in his accounts^*^ A remark- 
 able but rather indeterminate statement is supplied by the 
 oration against Euergus and Mnesibulus. The person for 
 whom this speech was written had been robbed by Theo- 
 phemus of fifty fine sheep, together with the shepherd, and 
 also a slave with a valuable water-pitcher, and some shep- 
 herd^s implements^*^ But the injured party was indebted to 
 Theophemus for a fine, which, together with Epobelia and 
 Prytaneia, amounted to 1313 drachmas and 2 oboH^*"; and 
 he maintains that the stolen sheep, together with the shepherd, 
 were worth more than the fine^^^ If we reckon the shepherd 
 at a very high rate, viz. at more than 3 minas, it results that 
 fifty sheep were worth 1000 drachmas; according to this 
 the price of a fine full-grown sheep was at the least 20 
 drachmas. Concerning the value of goats, which were very 
 plentiful in Attica, I have not been able to find any informa- 
 tion, except that in Iseeus^", a hundred goats, together with 
 sixty sheep, a horse, and some implements, are valued at 30 
 minas. As an example of luxury, it may be worth mentioning, 
 that Alcibiades gave 70 minas for a dog, which he shortly 
 afterwards deprived of its chief beauty"'. 
 
 3^« Aristoplu Pac. 373. 
 
 ^*^ Ap. Athen. iv. p. 140 E. viii. p. 
 364 D. 
 
 3*» Lysias cont. Diogit. p. 90G. 
 
 ^^^ See p. 1155. These sheep are 
 called TTpo^ara ^laXuKa. 
 
 "° See p. 1158, 24, p. 1162, 20, p. 
 1164, 10. 
 
 35' P. 1156, 15, 23, cf. p. 1164,5. 
 
 352 De Hagn. Hered. p. 293. The 
 passage in the Speech de Philoct. 
 llered. p. 140, is still more indefinite. 
 
 ^" Plutarch. Ale 0. Pollux v. 44.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 77 
 
 Chapter XV. 
 Prices of Corn and Bread, 
 
 On the subject of corn it will be necessary to enter into a more 
 detailed examination. The consumption of Attica required a 
 very considerable supply of corn. "No state/^ asserts Demos- 
 thenes, "consumes so large a quantity of imported corn^^*.^' The 
 Athenian ambassadors in Livy"^ boast of having supplied 
 100,000 measures, although their state was obliged even to 
 import corn for the use of the countrymen. But the main 
 points to which we must direct our attention are, in the first 
 place, what quantity of corn did Attica require ? secondly, how 
 much of this was it able to produce at home ? and, thirdly, 
 what quantity was it compelled to procure by importation ? 
 To answer these questions, the knowledge of which the Athe- 
 nians considered necessary in a statesman^^% is far more difficult 
 for us moderns, and yet is indispensable for an accurate insight 
 into the political and statistical relations of Attica. I now 
 undertake the solution of these problems, without presuming 
 to maintain that I may not fall into error. 
 
 According to the investigation in a former part of this 
 book, Attica may be assumed to have contained a population of 
 135,000 free inhabitants and 365,000 slaves'". An adult slave 
 received, according to accounts which can be fully depended 
 upon, a choenix, or the 48th part of an Attic medimnus, per 
 diem, and consequently consumed in a common year of 354 
 days 7f medimni. The Roman soldiers, according to Polybius, 
 received about the same quantity, that is to say, at the most f 
 of a medimnus of wheat per month. If we assume that among 
 the slaves there were 25,000 children, the 340,000 adults would 
 then consume 2,507,500 medimni a year. And if four medimni 
 a year are reckoned for a slave child, the total slave population 
 would have consumed 2,607,500 medimni. Among the free 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. de Corona, p. 254, 21, 
 and cent. Leptin. iit inf. 
 3" xliii. 6. 
 
 ^^^ Xenopli. Mem. Socrat. iii. 6, 13, 
 cf. Aristot. Rhet. i. 4. 
 ^^^ See above, ch. 7.
 
 78 PRICES OF CORN AXD BREAD. QbK. I. 
 
 inhabitants, one-half must be reckoned as children ; but the 
 adults also, as they were better fed than the slaves, pro- 
 bably did not consume so much corn. It will be enough to 
 reckon 2 medimni for a child, and 4 for an adult, altogether 
 405,000 medimni for 135,000 souls. According to this, the 
 whole consumption of a common year would amount to 
 3,012,500 medimni, or since an exact calculation is impossible, 
 in round numbers 3,000,000, exclusively of the seed corn, 
 which is more difficult to determine. If, again, it should be 
 alleged that a larger quantity than this must have been required 
 for the supply of the foreigners serving in the navy and the 
 army, it should be remembered that the absence of a large 
 number of soldiers and sailors from Athens would have had the 
 effect of lessening the consumption, as the army was chiefly 
 supplied from abroad. On the other hand, it can certainly 
 be conceded that the necessity of supplying their country with 
 imported provisions, increased the difficulty to the Athenians of 
 employing many mercenaries, who were also to be provided 
 with corn^^^. 
 
 Now that Attica did not produce these 3,000,000 medimni, 
 we know for certain ; and corn was brought from all quarters 
 into the market of the Piraeus, from the Pontus, Thrace, 
 Syria, Egypt, Libya, and Sicily^^^ It is well known that the 
 imports of corn from the Pontus were very considerable, which 
 M'as the cause that Byzantium was of so great importance to the 
 Athenians, and partly for that very reason Philip of Macedon 
 endeavoured to obtain possession of this town^^°. In the time 
 of Lysias private individuals imported corn from the Thracian 
 Chersonese, probably from the Athenian Cleruchiae^^^ Some 
 corn was brought from other countries by the Athenian merchants, 
 and part was supphed by Cyprus and Rhodes through the 
 medium of a carrying trade. From the former island there came 
 to Athens in the time of Andocides corn-vessels in considerable 
 numbers; of the latter, which was itself obliged to import corn, 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. ITcllen. vi. 1, 4. j chap, iv., and many scattered passages 
 
 ^" Theophrast de Plautis viii. 4. ; in the Orators. 
 See Anacharsis torn. iv. cliap. 55, | ^co Demosth. de Corona ut sup. 
 Wolf ad Lept. p. 253, ^Meui-sius F. A. ' ^ei Qf i^y^ ^ Diogit. p. 902.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF COHN AND BREAD. 
 
 n 
 
 and according to Polybius subsequently obtained it from Sicily, 
 we find an account in Lycurgus^*^ In addition to this. Euboea, 
 which was colonized with cleruchi in the time of Pericles and 
 Alcibiades, supplied corn and other products, which, before the 
 occupation of Decelea by the Spartans, were imported over 
 Oropus, but it subsequently became necessary to carry them in 
 ships round Cape Sunium, which was fortified on this account^^^. 
 A very large quantity of corn must consequently have been 
 imported, although it was not all for the internal consumption 
 of the country, but some to be sold in the Piraeus to foreigners. 
 This makes the statement of Demosthenes appear the more 
 unintelligible^", that the imports from the Pontus, which did 
 not amount to more than 400,000 medimni, might be taken as 
 nearly equal to the whole importation from other countries ; so 
 that the total of the imports would have been little more than 
 800,000 medimni, exclusively of that which was never unshipped, 
 but was transferred in the port of the Pireeus to other coun- 
 tries. Demosthenes appeals to the books of the Sitophylaces ; 
 but must we suppose that they agreed exactly with his words ? 
 All the Athenian orators, and even the noblest among them, 
 Demosthenes, distorted the truth without the least hesitation, 
 whenever it suited their own purposes. The total of the imports 
 may be fairly taken upon an average in round numbers at 
 1,000,000 medimni : but in particularly bad years, when even the 
 fertile Boeotia (at least after two successive years of deficient 
 harvests) required foreign supplies^®*, a much larger quantity was 
 doubtless necessary for the consumption of Attica. If we com- 
 pare this sum with the average number before assumed, it 
 follows that Attica must have produced 2,000,000 medimni, 
 which in my opinion was not impossible. The country, it is 
 true, is mountainous ; but the height of the mountains is not 
 
 ^^^ Andocid. de suo reditu p. 85, 
 86, Lycurg. c. Leocr. p. 149, Polyb. 
 xxviii. 2. 
 
 3«^ Tlmcyd. vii. 28, cf. viii. 4. 
 
 ^^* In Lept. p. 4G6, 4fl7. The words 
 wpos TOLVuv anavra top ck twi/ aWcov 
 i^TTopioiv a,(piKvoviievov 6 en tov Uovtov 
 
 (tItos ficTTrXecov earlv, do not signify 
 an equality, but only an approximation 
 in the quantity of the corn from the 
 Pontus to the supplies received from 
 other places, of which there is an evi- 
 dent proof in Herod, viii. 44, cf. 48. 
 ^^' Xenoph. Hellen. v. 4, 54.
 
 80 
 
 PRICES OF CORN' AND BREAD. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 SO considerable as to have made them necessarily barren ; the 
 naked rock, which was not indeed uncommon in Attica, com- 
 posed but a small portion of the area, and where the stony 
 bottom was mixed with a little earth, barley could be cultivated; 
 and art performed its share. 
 
 What portion of the area of Attica (amounting to 64,000 
 stadia, or 2,304,000 plethra) was corn-land, it is impossible 
 for me to ascertain ; but that it was possible for as much land 
 to be under the plough as was sufficient to produce 2,000,000 
 medimni, cannot easily be denied. In the territory of the 
 Leontini, in Sicily^^% the Roman jugerum, about two plethra 
 and tw^o-thirds, was sown wdth a medimnus of corn; that is, 
 about a bushel and a half of seed was reckoned for an acre 
 and a quarter, the jugerum being equal to 28,800 Roman, or 
 25,532 Rhenish, i.e. 34,468 English, feet. The fertile land 
 yielded in good years eightfold, in the best tenfold. If we 
 assume, as may be fairly done, the same measure of seed- 
 corn for Attica, and the increase on account of the inferior pro- 
 ductiveness of the soil as only sixfold (and even at the present 
 day, when agriculture has undoubtedly fallen off, the multipli- 
 cation of grain in Attica, according to Hobhouse^", is live and 
 six for one, and never more than ten), a plethron of land in 
 Attica produced two and a quarter medimni, and to produce 
 2,000,000 medimni 888,890 plethra of land were requisite, and 
 again for replacing the seed-corn 66,000 plethra besides. 
 According to these suppositions the land in corn must have 
 amounted to 955,500 plethra; the rest remained for fallow, 
 plantations, vines, (which were however frequently cultivated 
 together with barley, the branches of the vines being attached 
 to the trees,) leguminous plants, gardens, pasture-grounds, bog, 
 water, waste-land, roads, and dwellings. How little exaggerated 
 this supposition is, appears also to be proved from the fact, that 
 the property of Phsenippus, containing 1440 plethra of land, 
 although it was a boundary-estate with woods, produced yearly 
 
 °«« Cic. Verr. ii. 3, 47- 
 *' A Journey througli Albania and 
 other Provinces of Turkey in Europe 
 
 and Asia, to Constantinople, during 
 the years 1809 and 1810. By J, C. 
 Ilobhouse. London, 1813, vol. i.p.411.
 
 CIT. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AXD BREAD. 
 
 81 
 
 more than 1000 medimni of corn, and more fhan 800 metretae 
 of wine^®^ To general principles of political arithmetic I have 
 intentionally paid no regard, because, when applied to ancient 
 times, they only yield doubtful and uncertain conclusions ; and 
 still less will I institute a comparison \A'ith the produce of Lace- 
 dsemon, since the estimate which has been attempted to be 
 made from Plutarch^^^ is founded upon false assumptions. 
 
 With an importation equal to a third part of the consump- 
 tion, and in times of failure of the crops even this being insuffi- 
 cient, a great scarcity must necessarily have arisen^"", if judicious 
 arrangements had not been devised in order to prevent the 
 the occurrence of such an event. The arrangements for the 
 supply of corn were therefore conducted upon a large scale ; 
 Sunium was fortified, as has been remarked, in order to secure 
 the sailing of the corn vessels round the promontory; armed 
 ships convoyed the fleets laden with corn, as for example that 
 from the Pontus^"' ; when PoUis the Spartan was stationed near 
 Ceos, ^Egina, and Andros^ with sixty ships of war, Chabrias 
 offered him battle, in order that the corn from Gersestus in 
 Eubcea might reach the Pir8eus"^ The exportation of all 
 grain was absolutely prohibited : of the corn which arrived 
 from foreign parts in the harbour of Athens the law^ required 
 that two-thirds should be brought into the city, and compli- 
 ance with this regulation was enforced ])y the Overseers of 
 the Harbour''^; that is to say, only one-third could be car- 
 ried away to other countries from the port of the Piraeus. 
 In order to prevent the accumulation and hoarding of 
 
 -^8 Oral. c. Phaenipp. p. 1045, 5. 
 
 ^^^ Lycurg. 8. There were in Laco- 
 nia altogether 39,000 estates, of which 
 9000 were Spartan : one of these 
 estates brought the proprietor a return 
 of 82 medimni of barley, from which 
 the whole produce has been cal- 
 culated. It was not however per- 
 ceived that these 82 medimni were 
 only the tribe or rent of the Helots ; 
 nor is it certain whether the pas- 
 sage is to be understood of the Spartan 
 
 estates alone, or of the Lacedaemonian 
 also. 
 
 ^'^ Cf. e. g. Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 
 918, 8, c. Leptin. p. 467- 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. de Corona, p. 250, 251, 
 c. Polycl. p. 1211,25. 
 
 372 Xenoph. Hellen. v. 4, 61. Diod. 
 XV. 34. 
 
 3^3 Harpocr. in v. eVt/ifXj^rj)? ifxTTo- 
 plovy from Aristotle, and Lex. Seg. p. 
 255, where 'Kttikov should be written 
 instead of do-riKov, and the rest of the 
 article restored from Ilarpocration . 
 G
 
 82 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. [bK. I. 
 
 corn^^% engrossing was very much restricted; it was not permitted 
 to buy at one time more than fifty such loads as a man could 
 carry (</>op/xo/)'"'. The violation of this law was punished with 
 death. 
 
 The corn-dealers or the engrossers of corn were also compelled 
 to sell the medimnus for only one obolus more than the price 
 they themselves had given. Notwithstanding which regulations 
 these meuj who were for the most part aliens, raised the price 
 of corn by competition in bad times, and often sold it upon the 
 same day a drachma higher"'. Lysias cannot say enough of the 
 villany of these usurers, who were then as much detested as 
 they are in modern times. They bought up corn under the 
 pretence of providing for the interest of the people, or of having 
 an order from the proper authorities; but if a war-tax was 
 imposed, their pretended pubhc spirit did not show itself. The 
 public loss was their gain ; and so much did they rejoice at the 
 occurrence of any national calamity, that they never failed to 
 have the first intelligence of it ; or else they fabricated some 
 disastrous news, such as that the ships in the Pontus had been 
 taken or destroyed, that the trading-places were closed up, or 
 the treaties were broken off: even when external enemies were 
 at rest, they annoyed the citizens by buying up the corn, and 
 refusing to sell when it was most wanted, in order that people 
 might not contend with them about the price, but be content to 
 take it on their terms" ^ Nor did even the merchants make any 
 
 ^7-* Compare Plutarch, de Curiosit. j may tlierefore be fairly taken for a 
 ad fin. I man's load : thus the army of Lucul- 
 
 ^''' *op/z6y, from (pepo), generally ! lus, according to Plutarch, was followed 
 means a platted basket, in which corn by 30,000 Gauls, who carried 30,000 
 was probably carried. Taylor upon niedimni of corn. The explanations 
 Lysias compares with it the cumeras of the grammarians afford no infornia- 
 or cumera of the Romans, of which tion as to the size, but the notion of 
 there were two kinds, a greater and Petit that (popfibs is the same as Kocfiivos 
 a less; the latter contained 5 or 6 (/jj of the Attic medimnus) is absurd, 
 modii, i.e. about an Attic medimnus. 1 See Leg. Att. v. 5, 7. 
 See Acron ad. Ilorat. Sorm. i. 1, 53. | '76 g^g ^j^^ Speech of Lysias against 
 Probably at Athens the phorinus was the Corn-dealers, particularly p. 715, 
 not very different from the medim- 718, 720. 
 nus; a medimnus of wheat weighed I ^^^ l])\^^ pp_ 72O, 721, sqq. 
 from about 00 to 90 pounds, and |
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 profit by it, a circumstance upon which much stress is laid by 
 the modern teachers of political economy in favour of engross- 
 ing: on the contrary they suffered severe injury from the combi- 
 nations of the corn-dealers and their continual persecution^'^. 
 " If they were not menaced with the punishment of death/^ 
 says Lysias^^% " they would be scarcely endurable.^^ 
 
 Whilst, therefore, the sale of all other commodities was under 
 the inspection of the Agoranomi, the state, in order to check the 
 engrossing of corn, had set over this one branch of trade the 
 separate office of the Sitophylaces^^% which originally consisted 
 of three persons, afterwards of ten in the city and five in the 
 Piraeus, probably because their duties had increased. These 
 ofl&cers kept accounts of the imported corn, and it was also a 
 part of their duties to inspect the meal and bread, and to take 
 care that it was sold at the legal weight and price^^'. But even 
 the Sitophylaces could not at times control the importunate 
 competition on the part of the engrossers; and they were 
 punished with the greatest severity, and at times condemned 
 to death^^^ ; where we are as much startled at the irregularity of 
 
 ^'^ See the Speech of Lysias against 
 the Corn-dealers, pp. 72G, 727- 
 
 =^7« Ibid. p. 725. 
 
 3«» Ibid. p. 722. 
 
 3«^ Lysias iit sup. p. 717, mentions 
 three Sitophylaces. The other state- 
 ment rests upon the authority of Aris- 
 totle's state of Athens ap. Harpocrat. 
 in V. criTo^vXa/cey, where Valesius cor- 
 rectly reads rja-av de tov dpiOfiop 
 TrevTeKaldeKa- Se/ca fxev iv aarei, &c. 
 Sigonius R. A. iv. 3, silently follows 
 the first account; Petit v. 5, 7, per- 
 ceived the truth, but his emendation 
 is false with regard to the position of 
 the words, and §e<a is only to be re- 
 peated. Photius (in whose article for 
 apKTToi read aproi) has the same error ; 
 he moreover states that in later times 
 there were thirty (X') in the city, and 
 five in the Piraeus. All this is with- 
 out doubt to be attributed solely to 
 confusion, errors of the transcriber, 
 
 and the false emendation of previously 
 existing mistakes. The original pas- 
 sage, from wliicli tlie different accounts 
 were derived, was probably as follows : 
 rja-av be rbv apiOyiov Tvakai pev rpelsy 
 vcrrepop 6e TTCVTCKaideKa, d(Ka pev eu 
 aa-reif nevre de iv TLeLpaul. Their 
 duties may be seen from Demosth. 
 cont. Lept. ubi sup. Harpocrat. and 
 Lex. Seg. p. 300. The inspection of 
 bread and prepared corn, particularly 
 of barley meal (aXipira), occurs as 
 early as in the age of Pericles. See 
 the ancient comic poet ap. Plutarch. 
 Prtec. Polit. 15. 
 
 ^^^ Lysias ut sup. pp. 718, 723, 725, 
 extr. 726, init. Perhaps Demosth. 
 cont. Timocrat. p. 743, 4, also refers 
 to this subject, according to whom 
 persons who acted fraudulently in 
 dealings relating to corn were sen- 
 tenced to imprisonment. 
 
 G 2
 
 84 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 the corn-police, as at the severe administration of justice. A 
 still greater loss to the state was caused by the speculations of 
 the merchants, who, as Xenophon remarks'^', fetched corn from 
 diflferent parts, and did not sell it at the first place they arrived 
 at, but where they had ascertained the price to be highest. 
 Andocides^^* gives an account of a plot for turning the corn- 
 fleet from Cyprus, which was bound for Athens, in another 
 direction ; but he compelled the contrivers to relinquish their 
 plans. No one with regard to corn did Athens and the other 
 Grecian states so much injury as Cleomenes of Alexandria, 
 Alexander's satrap in Egypt, who accumulated large stores of 
 corn, fixed the prices arbitrarily, and on account of the number 
 of servants whom he had engaged in the corn -trade, was enabled 
 every where to ascertain the state of the market with accu- 
 racy. He mployed three d scriptions of persons, some who 
 despatched the corn, the attendants of the latter, and others 
 who received it and unshipped on the spot : accordingly he did 
 not allow his corn-vessels to touch at any commercial town 
 before his assistants in that place had given information with 
 regard to the state of the prices ; if they were high, the corn was 
 landed and sold, ^nd if not, the vessel proceeded to some other 
 place. By these means the corn at Athens rose considerably, 
 until the importation from Sicily produced a relief ^\ Of the 
 contrivances of this notorious corn-dealer the author of the 
 second book of the CEconomics, attributed to Aristotle, gives 
 some additional examples At a dear time, when the medimnus 
 sold for 10 drachmas, he convened the sellers for the purpose 
 of ascertaining from them at what price they would transfer 
 their corn to him ; upon their agreeing to sell it to him cheaper 
 than to the retail dealers, he gave them the same price, but 
 afterwards fixed the medimnus at 32 drachmas ! Upon the 
 occasion of a great scarcity in foreign countries, and even in 
 Egypt to a certain degree, he prohibited that any corn should 
 be exported ; upon the representation of the Nomarchs, that 
 
 38^ CEcon. 20, 27. 
 
 88* De suo reditu, pp. 85, 86. It is 
 almost unnecessary to mention that 
 
 Andocides was a merchant. 
 
 ^85 Demostli. cont. Dionysod. 
 1285.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 85 
 
 the taxes could not be paid if the exportation was not made 
 free, he permitted it, but at so high a duty, that the exports 
 were very limited; while the Nomarchs were deprived of their 
 pretext for not paying the taxes, and moreover a large sum was 
 raised from the export duty. 
 
 The Athenians endeavoured by various measures to ensure 
 or to increase the importation of corn. Of these was the 
 general law that no money should be lent upon any vessel 
 which did not bring to Athens a return-cargo of goods, among 
 which corn was expressly specified^^^ ; and also the more impor- 
 tant law, which provided that no person dwelling in Attica 
 should import corn to any other place than into the port of 
 Athens; the transgressor was subject to a Phasis, and also, 
 according to Lycurgus, to an Eisangelia, and consequently to the 
 punishment of death^^^. Theophilus^^^ asserts, that the corn- 
 dealers at Athens had enjoyed a freedom from taxes ; which 
 evidently cannot be understood of the times of its independence, 
 unless it was a transitory indulgence, or to a very limited 
 extent. For the term Ateleia has several significations ; it is 
 either a general immunity [arekeLa diravrcov), or a particular 
 exemption from the liturgies, or from certain custom-duties and 
 other taxes^^^ For example, the Athenians gave the universal 
 exemption from taxes to the Byzantian and Thracian refugees 
 who were resident at Athens in the time of Thrasybulus^^" ; 
 and to Leucon the ruler of the Bosphorus, who, together with 
 his sons, had an exemption from custom-duties, as is particu- 
 larly remarked"'. In this general Ateleia was comprised the 
 
 ^^^ See above, chap. ix. 
 
 387 Demosth. c. Pliorm. p. 918, 5, 
 cont. Lacrit. p. 941, 4, Lycurg. cont. 
 Leocr. p. 156, and the speech against 
 Theocrines. That the Phasis might 
 be instituted in such a case is certain 
 from the last-mentioned oration, from 
 -which (p. 1325, 28) it is to be particu- 
 larly remarked that the informer re- 
 ceived half the forfeited commodities. 
 Concerning the Phasis against this 
 offence see also the commentators of 
 Pollux viii. 47, and Lex. Seg. p. 313, 
 
 in V. <f)aiv€v, where the words rj efinopov 
 aX\ax66t epyaCofJievov can only be 
 referred to this practice. Concerning 
 the Eisangelia against this offence see 
 Matthise Miscell. Philog. torn. i. p. 
 231. 
 
 288 Theophil. i. 2, according to the 
 emendation of Salmasius de M. U. V. 
 p. 195, upon the authority of MSS. 
 
 383 See Wolf ad Lept. p. Ixxi. sqq. 
 
 ^^° Demosth. c. Lept. pp. 474, 475. 
 
 39' Demosth. c. Lept. pp. 466—468. 
 That he was free from custom-duties
 
 86 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 exemption from custom-duties, and from the liturgies (with the 
 exception of the trierarchy, which was only disallowed upon 
 certain conditions regulated by law), and for aliens from the 
 protection-money, and in particular cases from property-taxes ; 
 perhaps also the exemption from providing sacrifices {areXcLa 
 Upcov^), concerning which very little is known. That the corn- 
 merchants could not have enjoyed this universal immunity is 
 alone evident from the fact of their not having possessed several 
 of the individual exemptions. For, to say nothing of the 
 general immunity, they must in the first place have had an 
 exemption from the import duties upon corn ; now in Athens 
 the corn-duty was farmed ouf , and it must therefore have 
 entirely disappeared, if all corn-merchants had been allowed by 
 law to import corn free of duty ; the assertion in question does 
 not therefore require any refutation. It is still less conceivable 
 that they should have had permission to import or export other 
 goods free of duty, although individuals were allowed this 
 privilege for all or certain articles^'^ Were they, however, 
 exempted from the regular liturgies? Unquestionably not; 
 since, according to Demosthenes, so small a number either of 
 the citizens or resident-aliens were exempted from them^^\ 
 Moreover, this orator would not have omitted to point out the 
 prejudicial eifects which the abolition of the immunity of the 
 
 is evident from the comparison of the 
 immunity given to him and to his sons 
 with that granted by liim to all the 
 Athenians, p. 4G(j, 29. This complete 
 exemption appears to have been once 
 given to the Thebans and Olynthians 
 (Harpocrat. in v. 'lo-oreXjys), unless it 
 only means an exemption from protec- 
 tion-money and liturgies, in case they 
 should come as denizens to Athens, in 
 the same manner that the Byzantines, 
 in addition to the rights of citizenship, 
 gave an exemption from liturgies to all 
 Athenians going to Byzantium. See 
 the decree in Demosth. de Corona, p. 
 256, and compare the decree of the 
 Arcadians in Crete in Chisludl's Ant. 
 Asiat. p. 119. 
 
 '' " Mox vectigalia sacris faciundis a 
 Plothensibus pendenda memorantur : 
 a quibus ut immunitatem habeant, ex 
 publico solvuntur ea vectigalia. Hinc 
 vides qu£G sit dreXeia Upwv, quam 
 memorat Demosth. adv. Lept. § 105, 
 ed. F. A. Wolfii, in qua jure ha}sit 
 editor Proleg. p. Ixxi." Boeckh. ad 
 Inscript. 82, tom. i. p. 122. 
 
 ^^'^ See the speech against Nerera, p. 
 1353, 23. 
 
 ^^^ An instance of free exportation, 
 particularly of wood, which is undoubt- 
 edly to be referred to Athens, is fur- 
 nished by Theophrastus Char. 23. 
 I See, however, above, note 225. 
 Transl.] ' 
 
 ^^* Seebookiii. ch. 21.
 
 CB. XV.j 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 87 
 
 corn-merchants would have had upon the importation of corn, 
 if anything of the kind had existed ; for in the speech against 
 Leptines he searches for every argument against this aboUtion, 
 and particularly when speaking of Leucon^s Ateleia, he men- 
 tions the dangerous effect which the abolition of this exemption 
 might have upon the free exportation from the Bosporus. 
 Hence it may be concluded either that the immunity of the 
 corn-merchants had no real existence, or that it amounted to a 
 very trifling exemption. At the most it might be possible that 
 the resident-aliens who imported corn, were exempted from 
 certain degrading liturgies, such as the Scaphephoria and the 
 like, or from the protection-money^^^ Nor moreover is the 
 least credit due to the absurd assertion of the Scholiast to 
 Aristophanes^®^ that in Athens the merchants had an immu- 
 nity from all property-taxes. They were not even excepted 
 from the liturgies, an exemption which, it may be observed, 
 would have been extremely unfair; Andocides, notwithstand- 
 ing that he was a merchant, performed liturgies, though he was 
 not appointed upon his own offef^\ The statement of the 
 Scholiast is either an erroneous inference from the words of 
 the poet, or a misconception of the account of Euphronius, 
 upon whose authority he relies. The truth is, that those 
 who traded by sea had an exemption from serving in war, 
 although this privilege was probably circumscribed within 
 narrow limits^^\ Now since the exemption from military 
 service is also called Ateleia^^^, it seems to me most probable, 
 that when Theophilus speaks of the immunity of the corn-mer- 
 chants, he means nothing more than this exemption, which was 
 granted alike to all merchants. 
 
 Athens had public warehouses for corn in the Odeum, the 
 
 ^^* Concerning the latter see book 
 iii. cli. 7- 
 
 3^« Plut. 905, cf. Eccles. 1019. 
 
 ^^7 Andocid. de Myst. p. 65, cf. 
 Inscript. ap. Chandler ii. 6, p. 48, Vit. 
 X. Orat. p. 229. 
 
 39" Tliis is stated by the Scholiast 
 himself and bySuidas in v. efirropos et/xt 
 
 rrKrjTTTOIXfPOS. 
 
 ^^^ Yid. Orat. cont. Neaer. ubi sup. 
 Whether, however, the immunity from 
 military service was comprised under 
 the tlreXfia a7rdvT<ov, may be fairly 
 doubted, although military service was 
 included among the TeXrj ; at least I 
 do not venture to assume it without 
 express testimony to the point.
 
 88 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND HREAT). 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 Pompeum, the long Porch, and at the naval storehouse near the 
 sea, where corn, bread, &c., were sold to the people'"''. It is 
 not, however, quite clear, wli ether this magazine was used 
 exclusively for corn which belonged to the state, or whether 
 grain was there measured out which v.as the proi)erty of private 
 merchants. There are some grounds for considering the 
 latter notion as the more probable'"'. It is at least certain that 
 considerable stores were brought to Athens at the expense of 
 the state, which must have been kept in these warehouses. This 
 corn was in part purchased with the public money, and partly 
 by voluntary contributions : a merchant named Chrysippus 
 boasted of having given a talent for that purpose ; Demosthenes 
 also presented an equal sum''^ Certain persons named Sitonee 
 were appointed to superintend the purchase, Avhose office was 
 not considered unimportant, as it implied the entire confidence 
 of the people ; there were also Apodectee, whose duty it was to 
 receive the corn and to measure it out. The former situation was 
 once filled by Demosthenes ; and it was perhaps at that time 
 that he gave the voluntary contribution already mentioned'*'^ 
 It was doubtless sold to the people at a very low price, as 
 otherwise these donations of money would have been unneces- 
 sary ; perhaps too the corn brought to Athens was at times 
 distributed ^.ratis. But the want of adequate information 
 renders it impossible to form any certain conclusion ; for even 
 when the reader hopes that he has at length met with a state- 
 ment which may be depended upon, the ambiguity of the 
 expression and the difficulty of interpretation, oppose insuper- 
 able difficulties in his way. Thus Demosthenes, in tlie speech 
 against Leptines, relates that two years before, during a scarcity 
 of corn, Leucon had sent so large a quantity and at so cheap a 
 
 *"" Demostli. cont. Phorin. p. 918. 
 Concerning the public sale of corn see 
 also Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 103, con- 
 cerning the Odeum see Lex. Seg. p. 
 318, and upon the magazines of corn 
 P»llux ix. 45, with the commentators. 
 
 **" From Demosth. ut sup. p. 018, 
 24—26. 
 
 •"''' Demosth. cont. rhorm.' p. 918, 
 27. First decree at the end of the 
 Lives of the Ten Orators. Theophrast. 
 Cliar. 23, does not appear to refer to 
 this point. 
 
 '»' Pollux viii. 114, Demosth. de 
 Corona, p. ."lO, I.
 
 CII. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORX AND HUE AD. 
 
 m 
 
 rate, that fifteen talents, of which Callistlienes had the manage- 
 ment, remained as a surplus. It may, however, be doubted 
 whether a clear surplus actually remained, in the sense in which 
 the commentators understand it, viz., tliat these fifteen talents 
 formed a portion of the money set apart for the purchase of 
 corn, which had not been entirely consumed ; or whether we 
 are not rather to understand that as the corn had been bought 
 up at a low price, this sum remained as a net surplus profit to 
 the state, after the corn had been sold to the people'"'^ To 
 this donation of corn an account of Strabo has been with much 
 apparent probability referred"' ; for the context show^s that he 
 nmst allude to some particular distribution of corn, inasmuch 
 as he states expressly that Leucon had sent 2,100,000 medimni 
 to the Athenians from Theudosia ; and it is possible that this 
 took place within the space of one year. For since Attica 
 consumed 3,000,000 medimni, of which in the regular course 
 of things it was required to produce 2,000,000, a failure of the 
 crops might easily for once have caused the produce of the 
 country to fall oflF to half the usual amount; and while the 
 other countries, w^hich also felt the effects of the general 
 scarcity, were unable to furnish any supplies^ Leucon alone 
 made up the deficiency. 
 
 On particular occasions free distributions of com took 
 place at Athens {atToSoaiai), such as were very frequent in 
 Rome ; the object of them being in both places to pacify the 
 people"^ The presents in particular, which w^ere at times 
 
 *^* The passage is as follows (p. 467, 
 14 — 17): 'AXXa Trponepvai airodeias 
 napa tvuctlv dvOpatTTois yei/o/xeVr/s ov 
 fiovou vp-lv LKavov (t'itov aTT€(rT€LkcV, 
 dWa TocrovTOV aare TreuTeicaideKa dpyv- 
 piov ToXam-a, a KaWiadevrjS dicaKijae, 
 npoo-rrepiyevecrOaL. Toaovrov should 
 e\-idently be written with Hier. Wolf, 
 and compare the note of F. A Wolf 
 ad Lept. pp. 257, 258. The date of 
 the occurrence is Olymp. 105, 4 (357 
 B.C.) The chief ambiguity lies in the 
 word TrpocnrepLyevea-dai. It might be 
 said that if Demosthenes had only 
 wished to signify the residue of the 
 
 money appointed for purchasing com, 
 he would have said Trepiyepeadai ; and 
 that 7rpocr7repiy€V€a6ai shows that the 
 excess was gained, viz. by the sale of 
 com to the citizens ; but I do not 
 venture to found any arguments upon 
 this supposition. It must not be sup- 
 posed that the com was sold abroad. 
 
 *^o vii. p. 215. 
 
 *«« Aristoph. Vesp. 714. The word 
 aiTodoaia occurs in Pollux viii. 103, 
 Avho observes from Andocides that 
 checking-clerks {dvTiypa<pels) were em- 
 ployed for some purposes connected 
 with it.
 
 90 PRICES OF CORN AND BR£AD. [bK. I. 
 
 made to the people from foreign parts, were distributed 
 gratis. Thus Demetrius PoHorcetes, in Olymp. 118, 2 (307 
 B.C.), promised to the Athenians 150,000 medimni of corn as 
 a present from his father. Thus Spartocus, the son of Eumelus, 
 king in the Bosporus, who reigned twenty years from Olymp. 
 119, 1 (304 B.C.), sent 10,000 medimni to the grateful people 
 of Athens'"^ So again in Olymp. 83, 4 (445 B.C.), in the 
 Archonship of Lysimachides, the Athenians during a scarcity 
 of corn received from an Egyptian of the name of Psammeti- 
 chus, who was not known to them, 40,000 medimni of wheat, 
 which were distributed among the genuine citizens*"". With 
 this distribution the Scholiast to Aristophanes""^ confounds 
 another, in which each] citizen received 5 medimni of barley, 
 although he himself perceives that from 40,000 medimni 14,240 
 citizens could not have each received 5 medimni. The 
 donation of which Aristophanes speaks, took place in Olymp. 
 89, 1 (424 B.C.), one year before the Wasps of the same poet, 
 when, in the Archonship of Isarchus, an expedition was under- 
 taken against Euboea. At that time it was probably expected 
 that large supplies w^ould be derived from this island, and 50 
 medimni of corn had therefore been promised to each citizen, 
 a new scrutiny being also instituted into the genuineness of 
 their births ; after all, however, they only received 5 me- 
 dimni*'". The division of the lands in Eubcea, which Aris- 
 
 *°'' Plutarch. Demetr. 10; Diod. xx. Eumelus, is mentioned in an inscrip- 
 46; Attic Decree in Corp. Inscript. tiou. More however of these well- 
 Gr. No. 107. Concerning the time of known princes elsewhere. It may be 
 Spartocus, or, as Diodorus incon-ectly observed that by Bosporus and Pontus 
 calls him, Spartacus, see Diod. xx- the same kingdom is signified. [See 
 100. The same person is mentioned Boeckli, Corp. Inscript. Gr. vol. ii. 
 in two inscriptions found at Phana- p. 90-4. Traxsl.] 
 goria, Corp. Inscript. Gr. Nos. 2120, ""^ Philocliorus ap. Schol. Aristoph. 
 2120 b. Another more ancient Spar- Vesp. 716, where d' fxvpiddas should 
 tocus occurs in Diod. xii. 31, 36 (where be written from Phitarch. Pericl. 37. 
 see the Conmientators), also king of ; Concerning the number of the citizens 
 the Cimmerian Bosporus, another in , comp. above chap. 7. 
 xiv. 93, and again another as king in | ^°^ Ubi sup. 
 
 the Pontus in Diod. xvi. 52, who was | ^'" Aristophanes in the text, where 
 succeeded by his brother Pairisades. } the words ^eulas (f)€vyo3p allude to the 
 A Spartocus, father of Pairisades, j examinations into the legal claims of 
 perhaps the same with the son of j the citizens, which were made witli
 
 CH. XV.] PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. SI 
 
 tophanes expressly distinguishes from this donation of com, 
 was perhaps promised at the same time. The donation of 
 corn made by Atticus to the people, at the time of their severe 
 distress, is also a well-known circumstance"*'. 
 
 Before I attempt to ascertain the prices of corn, something 
 must be said upon the measures by which it was sold. The 
 Attic corn-medimnus {/jLeBt/jLvos airrjpos) contained, according 
 to the division commonly used in trade, 6 sextarii (e/crety) 
 or 48 choenices, or 192 cotylas {KorvXac) : this last was used 
 both as a dry and a liquid measure*^*. Pollux in the fourth 
 book reckons 3 cotylas instead of 4 to a choenix, which belongs 
 to some other mode of computhig than that in use among 
 the Athenians. A choenix was the common daily allow- 
 ance of food (r)fjL€pr]<TLa Tpo<^riY^^, particularly for slaves, from 
 which circumstance the Corinthians, who had a great number 
 of slaves, are said to have been called choenix-measurers by the 
 Pythian priestess"^*. An athlete indeed was able, according 
 to Theophrastus, to consume 2i Attic choenices a day; 
 and if Aglais required for one meal 12 minas of meat and a 
 chus of wine, it is natural that she should eat 4 choenices of 
 wheaten bread. This woman was a player on the trumpet of 
 great celebrity ; Herodorus of Megara, also a famous trumpeter, 
 consumed 6 choenices of wheaten bread each day, 8 minas 
 of meat, or according to another authority 20 minas, and 
 drank twice as much as the former person"'^ ; not to mention 
 many other gluttons, whose names may be found in Athenaeus. 
 The Spartans also, who lived upon meagre food, appear to have 
 
 great strictness on these occasions, choenix was but a small quantity ; but 
 Concerning the Archon, under whom 
 the expedition was undertaken, see 
 Palmer Exercit. in Auct. Grcec. p. 
 738. Compare also the Fragments of 
 Philochorus, in the edition of Lenz 
 and Siebelis, pp. 51, 52. 
 *^i Nepos Att. 2. 
 
 it must be remembered that he is 
 speaking of soldiers, who would natu- 
 rally consume a large quantity, and 
 that there were also many persons of 
 distinction among them, Suidas in v. 
 Uvdayopa to. av^lBoXa rjv rtiSe, A then. 
 iii. p. 90 E. 
 
 "'^ Pollux X. 113; iv. 168 ; vii. 195; *^^ Athen. vi. p. 272 B. 
 of. Athen. xi. p. 479 F. I ^'^ .^lian. Y. Jl. 5. 26; Pollux iv. 
 
 ■*'=* See Herod, vii. 187, from which I 89 ; Athen. x. p. 415 F; XiVp.i in 
 it might indeed be inferred tliat a Athenaeus is the same as ^vd.
 
 92 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 eaten much ; each person was therefore bound to furnish 
 monthly a medimnus of barley-meal to the pubUc entertain- 
 ment, together with a scanty portion of other provisions. The 
 x\thenian prisoners in the quarries of Syracuse received only 
 half a choenix, i.e. 2 cotylas of barley and 1 cotyla of 
 water, which allowance was continued for eight months'" ^ 
 That with this scanty food many of them perished in the first 
 seventy days from hunger and thirst is not to be wondered at, 
 particularly as barley contains but little nourishment^'^. The 
 size of these several measures immediately follows from the 
 determination of the medimnus. Without paying any regard 
 to the false statements of Eisenschmid and Rome de FIsle, or 
 to the ambiguous calculation of Rambach, I follow the account 
 given by Ideler, which can alone be depended upon. The 
 Athenian medimnus then, like the Sicilian, contained 6 Ro- 
 man modii^^^; but the modius, according to a decree of the 
 people preserved in Festus, contained 16, the amphora 48 
 sextarii ; consequently the Athenian medimnus contained about 
 2 amphorae, which is also shown by the testimony of Rhem- 
 nius Fannius''^^ But the amphora or quadrantal was the 
 Roman cubic foot, which as the Roman foot of long measure 
 is nearly equal to 131 Paris lines, contained 1301 Paris cubic 
 inches. The medimnus was therefore about equal to 2602 
 French or 3150*059 English cubic inches (for it can hardly be 
 supposed that the ratio of the modius to the medimnus was 
 precisely as 6 to 1); and the English pint of dry measure 
 containing 33'6 cubic inches, the medimnus of 3150 cu])ic 
 
 ^'® Concerning the Spartans see 
 Plutarch. Lycurg. 12. Of the pri- 
 soners in Syracuse, Thuc. vii. 87 ; 
 Plutarch. Nic. 29 ; cf. Eustath. ad II. 
 X. p. 1282, 15. Diodoi-us xiii. 33, 
 asserts that the proposal of Diodes 
 was accepted, that the captive Athe- 
 nians, Sicilians, and Italians should 
 work in prison, and receive 2 choe- 
 nices a day (xiii. 19) ; but although 
 he here speaks of a different period, 
 viz. when they were brought out of 
 the stone-quarricSj and separated from 
 
 the other prisoners, he does not de- 
 serve the least credit, and he has pro- 
 bably confounded 2 cotylas with 2 
 chcenices. 
 
 ^'7 Athen. iii. p. 115. 
 
 *'8 Nepos Att. 2 ; Cic. Verr. Fru- 
 ment. 46, 49 ; Suidas in v. fiedifivov, 
 from which passage correct Zonaras 
 in the same word. 
 
 "•'^ Hujus (amphorne) dimid'ium fert 
 urna, ut et ipsa, mcdimni amphora, 
 terqne capit modium.
 
 CII. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 :93 
 
 inches is equal to 93*75 pints, or 1 bushel 3 gallons 5*75 pints, 
 i. e. nearly a bushel and a half. 
 
 Of other corn measures, consistently with my plan, I shall 
 only touch upon the artabe and the Boeotian cophinus. The 
 former was a Persian measure, and contained, according to Hero- 
 dotus^^", an Attic medimnus and 3 choenices. Others fix it at an 
 approximate valuation as equal to the Attic medimnus"^'. It was 
 also in use in Egypt, where there was besides a smaller artabe, 
 which only contained 3^ Roman modii or 26 1 Athenian choe- 
 mces'*^^ If the capacity of this measure is doubled, it gives 53 J 
 Athenian choenices, which differs so little from the value of the 
 greater artabe in Herodotus (51 choenices), that, as it appears, we 
 may fairly assume the smaller artabe to have been exactly half 
 the greater, and suppose either that the statement of Herodotus 
 is too low, or that the valuation of the smaller artabe at 34 
 Roman modii is somewhat too high, or, lastly, that the ratio 
 of the Athenian medimnus to the Roman modius has been 
 estimated a fraction too low. The Boeotian cophinus, which 
 was used bjth as a wet and dry measure, contained 3 choeis*^% 
 L e. a quarter metretes, or 36 cotylas, since the metretes con- 
 tained 144 cotylas, which is equivalent to 9 choenices, or -^-^ 
 medimnus of Athenian measure. 
 
 The prices of different kinds of corn were, as may be sup- 
 posed, very different. In Sicily and Upper Italy the price of 
 barley was only half that of wheat, in Athens probably, as 
 in Lusitania, it amounted to two-thirds of the price of the 
 latter ^^^; but where the price of corn is mentioned, the par- 
 ticular description of grain is not always specified. It may be 
 seen from examples, that the prices from the time of Solon to 
 that of Demosthenes were continually rising ; yet again there fre- 
 quently existed at the same period a great fluctuation, according 
 to the greater or less productiveness of the years, the increase 
 
 ^^ i. 192. 
 
 *^^ Suidas, Hesycliius, Polysen. 
 3, 32 ; Epiphanius Ponder. 24. 
 ^^ Wesseling ad Diod. xx. 90. 
 
 •'^^ Pollux iv. IC9 ; Hesych. in 
 k6(^ivos. 
 
 ■^^^ Concerning Upper Italy and 
 Lusitania see above chap. 10. I will 
 speak of Sicily and Athens presently.
 
 94 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 or diminution in the imports, the prejudicial efforts of the 
 engrossers both in and out of Attica, or the imposition of high 
 custom-duties in foreign parts, or the accidental remission of 
 them to the Athenians ; thus Leucon and Pairisades, kings of 
 the Bosporus, the former of whom used to levy a duty of a thir- 
 tieth upon all exported corn, granted to the Athenian people an 
 exemption from this tax*". Prices at Athens were never again 
 so low as in the time of Solon, when the medimnus was sold for 
 a drachma **^ Barley-meal {a\(f>iTa) was sold in the age of 
 Socrates at 2 drachmas the medimnus, and at an obolus for 
 
 4 choenices*^^; by which however we are not to understand 
 meal prepared after the modern way. Diogenes the Cynic 
 reckons, that in his age the choenix of barley-meal sold at 2 
 chalcus, and consequently the medimnus at 2 drachmas'**^: 
 but this can only refer to the cheapest years, for at this period 
 the common price at Athens was much higher. In a play of 
 Aristophanes*^® a man declares that he has lost a hecteus of 
 wheat, by not having gone to the assembly, and consequently 
 not receiving his 3 oboli ; whence it may be concluded that 
 about the 96th and 97th Olympiads (396-2 B.C.), the medimnus 
 of wheat sold for 3 drachmas, which agrees very well with 
 the price of barley just quoted. But in the time of Demos- 
 thenes, and even after Alexander's expedition against Thebes, 
 
 5 drachmas were a moderate price, at which during a scarcity some 
 of the more liberal corn-dealers sold their wheat : thus Chry- 
 sippus sold 10,000 medimni at this price *^". According to the 
 speech against Phsenippus*^', even barley must have been at 
 
 6 drachmas for a long time, as 18 drachmas are stated to be 
 three times the former price. The prices in other Grecian 
 States were not very different. In the second book of the 
 CEconomics attributed to Aristotle, it is stated that the price 
 of barley-meal at Lampsacus was 4 drachmas, but that the 
 
 "^5 Demosth. c. Lept. p. 4G7, c. 
 Phorra. p. 917, 25. 
 
 *^6 Plutarcli. Solon. 23. 
 
 ^^"^ Plutarch, de Animi Tranquil- 
 lltate 10, Stob. Senn- xcv. p. 521. 
 Conip. Barth^emy in the Mem. de 
 
 TAcad. des Inscriptions, torn. xLviii. 
 p. 394, concerning the price of corn. 
 
 ■*^« Diog. Laert. vi. in Vit. Diog. 
 
 •*-^ Eccles. 543. 
 
 "'" Demosth. cont. Pliorm. p. 918. 
 
 *3' P. 1048, 24.
 
 CH. XV.] PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 95 
 
 state once fixed it upon a particular occasion at 6 drachmas, 
 in order to obtain a profit on the difference. When Sicily- 
 came under the Roman dominion, the latter people fixed for 
 supplies the Frumentum Decumanum Alterum at 3 sesterces 
 for each modius, the Imperatum and ^stimatum of wheat at 
 
 4 and of barley at 2 sesterces the modius; a price which 
 must at that time have been moderate, as the Romans would 
 doubtless have fixed a low rate, although, according to the 
 statement of Cicero, it was not insupportable to the cultivators. 
 Consequently the medimnus of the Decumanum Alterum cost 
 at that time 4 drachmas the medimnus, of the Imperatum 
 and ^Estimatum of barley 2 drachmas 4 oboli, and of wheat 
 
 5 drachmas 2 oboli of Attic money. If these high prices 
 should seem startling, we must remember how dense was 
 the population of this country and how large the exportation. 
 In earlier times, however, corn, as may be inferred from the 
 price of cattle*^*, must have been much cheaper in Sicily; and 
 subsequently, as for example in the time of Verres, prices did 
 not attain even this height, on account of the decreasing popu- 
 lation of the cities ; the medimnus of wheat was commonly 
 sold at that time for 12 sesterces, or 2 drachmas 4 oboli, 
 and never rose to more than 15 sesterces, or 3 drachmas 4 
 oboli "^ It is also to be observed that in the prices of the 
 supplies of Sicilian corn, as the Romans had fixed them, the 
 cost of transport to each separate place of destination was like- 
 wise included. Such prices as the following are extraordinary, 
 viz.: when corn rose at Athens to 16 and even barley to 
 18 drachmas; also at Rome in the year of the city 544 
 (210 B.C.), the Sicilian medimnus of corn was sold, accordhig to 
 Polybius, at 15 drachmas, or rather denarii; and in Dolla- 
 bella^s army, from which the supplies in the neighbourhood of 
 Laodicea were cut off, the medimnus of wheat was sold for 
 12 drachmas"*. From a very corrupt passage of Strattis pre- 
 served in Pollux*", so much at least may be gathered, that a 
 
 *^^ See above, chap. xiv. 
 
 «3 Cic. Yen-. Frument. 74, 75, 81, 84. 
 
 *^* Demosth. cont. Phorm. p. 918, 
 
 ix. 44, Cic. ad Fam. xii. 13. 
 
 ■*35 Pollux iv. 169. Petit, ui sup. 
 reckons from this passage the medim- 
 
 Orat. cont. Phsenipp. p. 1045,4, Polyb. | nus at 128 dracl
 
 96 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND IJREAD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 slave, to the great astonishment of his master, pretends to have 
 bought a Boeotian cophinus of barley-meal for 4 drachmas, 
 which gives for the medimnus 21 drachmas 2 oboli ; and it 
 may be inferred from the same grammarian that another writer 
 spoke of wheat being sold for 32 drachmas, without doubt refer- 
 ring to the usurious practices of Cleomenes, which I have 
 already noticed *^'^; not to mention that at Athens during the 
 siege of Sulla, the medimnus of wheat rose to a thousand 
 drachmas, the inhabitants being reduced to feed even on shoes 
 and leathern-bottles; and in like manner at Casilinum, where 
 the Praenestini were besieged by Hannibal, the same measure 
 was sold for 200 drachmas ''^^ 
 
 The varieties of bread were extremely numerous in Greece, 
 and the invention of the Athenians in particular was directed 
 with great success to this department of the culinary art*-^ 
 Atheneeus and Pollux will suppl)^ the amateur of the arts of 
 cookery and baking with sufficient materials for inquiries, which 
 we neither feel disposed nor entitled to enter upon. The most 
 common distinction is between wheaten-bread [apros) and 
 barley-bread {/jud^a) : a\(j)tTa sometimes means barley-meal 
 itself, and sometimes a bread or rather cake made of barley- 
 
 436 Pollux iv. 165, where there stood 
 formerly the word TpiaKovrabibpaxfJ-i- 
 TTvpyoi, an uncouth form, which Pe- 
 titus however retained, and proposed 
 to change to TpiaKovrabibpaxp-oTrupyoL. 
 The reading of Voss's manuscript, 
 rpiaKovrabldpaxpoi Trvpoi, is evidently 
 the right one, and consequently the 
 price of wheat is meant : manifestly 
 that which was fixed by Cleomenes. 
 The present reading in the text, 6i- 
 dpaxp-oi, is entirely without found- 
 ation, as well as Kuhn's conjecture, 
 TpiaKaidcKadpaxpoi : rpLKovrddpaxpoi, 
 the correction of Jungermann, has in- 
 deed some probability ; however I con- 
 sider the reading of Vosss manuscript 
 to be correct for this reason, tliat the 
 use of the singular compound rpiaKov- 
 rahlbpaxp-OL instead of bvoKaLTpiaKovra- 
 dpaxpoi appears to be the very reason 
 
 why Pollux quotes the word. 
 
 ^37 See Plutarch Sulla 13, and Strabo 
 V. p. 1G4, where in the account of Ca- 
 silinum the medimnus is mentioned 
 alone, without the thing measured, 
 which ought never to have appeared 
 surprising to so excellent a scholar as 
 Casaubon, as it so frequently occurs. 
 Pliny, Frontinus, and Valerius ^laxi- 
 mus substitute indeed a mouse in the 
 place of this measure, but Strabo had 
 too much judgment to say, as the 
 Commentators impute to him, that 200 
 drachmas were given for a mouse, and 
 that the sellers died, but that the 
 buyers saved their lives. We must 
 indeed, if this story be true, suppose 
 that great events spring from little 
 causes. 
 
 *^« A then. iii. p. 112, c. &c.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PRICES OF CORN AND BREAD. 
 
 9? 
 
 meal, of a very fine quality *^^ I have not however been able 
 to meet with any clear statement in reference to the price of 
 bread, but it was probably high in proportion to that of corn ; 
 for, if we may judge from the rate of interest, a great profit 
 must have been obtained upon the capital employed in the pre- 
 paration of bread. At Athens four large and eight small loaves 
 used to be baked out of a choenix of corn ; consequently one 
 large or two small loaves out of a cotyla"*"; in dear times, when 
 for example corn was at 16 drachmas, a loaf of wheaten- 
 bread of this kind, probably a large one of a cotyla, might have 
 sold for an obolus : to which ' may be referred the fact, that at 
 the very same time wheaten-bread was sold in the Pireeus in 
 loaves of an obolus "^ At Alexandria the apros offeXias or 
 6/36\lt7]9, was sold for an obolus ""% and probably the same was 
 the case at Athens ''*% which however gives no information with 
 regard to the price, as the size is unknown ; and this Alexan- 
 drian bread was not of the ordinary kind, but something more 
 costly, which is opposed to the common wheaten-bread^^*. 
 There were also loaves of a much larger size, for instance of 
 3 choenices"*'; and at the Dionysia they carried around in 
 honour of the divine inventor, loaves of from 1 to 3 medimni, 
 which w^ere likewise called aproi oPeXlau^'^^, 
 
 *^ Omitting other passages, I only 
 refer to Xenoph. (Econ. 8, 9, Plat. 
 Rep. ii. p. 372, B, Pollux vi. 78. Con- 
 cerning the word ^d^a see below, 
 chap, xxiii. 
 
 ^*^ Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 438, Ly- 
 sistrat. 1208. 
 
 '**' Demosth. cont. Plionn. p. 918. 
 
 **^ Concerning which bread and its 
 price see PoUux i. 248, and in other 
 places, Athen. iii. p. 111. B, who lias 
 been transcribed by Eustath. ad II. N. 
 p. 930, ad Odyss. A. p. 39, 38. 
 
 ^^^ If the interpretation of o^oXias 
 fiprovs in Anstophanes given in Lex. 
 Seg. p. Ill, is correct. 
 
 444 Pherecrates ap. Athen. nbi sup. 
 and Nicochares the comic poet, ibid. 
 xiv. p. 645, C. It may be observed 
 that the supposition, which is men- 
 
 tioned in Athenseus, and thence in 
 Eustathius, and which occurred to 
 Sober ad Poll. i. 248, that this bread 
 received its name from the price, is 
 extremely improbable, although o/3eX6j 
 and d^oXos are the same word, and 
 originally meant a fork or spit, and, 
 afterwards the coin so called. See 
 Plutarch. Lysand. 17, Pollux ix. 77,- 
 and the Commentators, EtjTnol. in 
 olSekiaKoSj also the Commentators upon 
 Athenteus ubi sup. and Taylor ad 
 ;Marm. Sandw. p. 49. It was no doubt 
 so called from the forks or long pieces 
 of wood upon whicli it was baked in 
 the ashes. See Athen. iii. ubi sup. 
 and the Commentators, Photiusp,229. 
 
 "5 Xenoph. Anab. vii. 3, 23. 
 
 "^'^ Pollux vi. 75, cf. Eustath. 
 
 H
 
 P$ PRICES OF WINE, OIL, SALT, AND WOOD. [bK. I. 
 
 Chapter XVL 
 Prices of Wine, Oil, Salt, and Wood, 
 
 The common measure for liquids was the metretes, which con- 
 tained 12 choeis or 144 cotylas, and to which the common 
 vessel {afjb<f>opevs, KaBos, Kepd/jLiov) was adapted. The Roman 
 amphora, or the solid foot, was according to the testimony of 
 Rhemnius Fannius f of the Attic metretes : but the Attic 
 medimnus is the double of the amphora; consequently the 
 metretes was f of the Attic medimnus, which is also evident 
 from its being equal to 144 cotylas. The contents of the 
 medimnus were in a former place ascertained to have been 2602 
 Paris inches, and therefore the metretes is equal to 2362*5 
 English cubic inches, or 81*818 pints, i. e, 10 gallons If pints 
 of wine measure. Who then is not astonished at the extraor- 
 dinary cheapness of wine in ancient times, upon reading of such 
 prices, as have been already quoted with regard to Lusitania, at 
 which more than ten gallons of unmixed wine sold for Sd. ? 
 And since the ancients allowed one part of wine to two of 
 water, without intending to dilute it much, ten gallons of such 
 liquor were sold for a penny. The common wine must there- 
 fore have been looked upon as the cheapest of all necessaries, 
 the causes of which phenomenon have been already stated. 
 
 In Lusitania the metretes of wine appears to have been 
 equal in price to the medimnus of barley, but at Athens it seems 
 to have been even cheaper than barley ; for according to the 
 speech against Phsenippus, when prices were three times higher 
 than usual, barley was sold at 18 and the native Athenian wine 
 at 12 drachmas"". Therefore, according to the usual price, 
 the metretes of wine was sold for 4 drachmas; even this rate, 
 however, as well as 6 drachmas for a medimnus of barley, 
 must have been considered dear ; there would be no danger of 
 exaggeration, if the half of this price were assumed as an ave- 
 rage for cheaper times. In an agreement in Demosthenes*" 
 3000 casks {Kepdfjuia) of Mendsean wine are estimated at 6000 
 
 "^7 Orat. cont. Phaenipp. p. 1018, 24. *'^ Cont. Lacrit. p. 928, extr.
 
 CH. XVI.] PRICES OF WINE, OIL, SALT, AND WOOD, 
 
 99 
 
 drachmas, that is, the cask of the metretes came to 2 
 drachmas, although Mendsean wine was used even at the most 
 sumptuous entertainments of the Macedonians**'. It is men- 
 tioned by Polybius**" that the Rhodians bought for the Sino- 
 pians, when the latter were invaded by Mithridates in Olymp. 
 179. 4 (61 B.C.), for the sum of 140,000 drachmas, 10,000 
 casks of wine {fcepdfMta), 300 talents of prepared hair, 100 
 talents of prepared strings, 1000 complete suits of armour, 4 
 catapults with darts and attendants, and 3000 gold coins. 
 Whence it is easy to perceive that this could only have been 
 possible in case the price of wine did not exceed that which 
 has been above-mentioned. According to the grammarians, 3 
 cotylas of the wine which was called tricotylus was sold at an 
 obolus*" ; which gives for the metretes 8 drachmas. This 
 therefore was either of a superior sort, or it only appears dearer 
 because the retail-dealers [KainfkoL), who sold it by the obolus, 
 added considerably to the price. On the other hand there were 
 also very costly wines ; for example the Chian wine, as early as 
 in the time of Socrates, sold for a mina the metretes"*. 
 
 Oil, although it was produced- in large quantities in Attica, 
 Asia Minor, and the islands, appears to have maintained a higher 
 price on account of the great demand for it in ancient times, for 
 the purposes of light, for dressing meat, and for the gymnasia; 
 yet as regards the Greeks I have only been able to find a single 
 statement of its price, and this is given in the second book of 
 the CEconomics attributed to Aristotle*", where it is stated that 
 
 *^» Athen. iv. p. 129, D, to omit 
 other passages concerning the good- 
 ness of this wine. 
 
 **o iv. 56. 
 
 "^ Schol. Aristoph. Thesmoph. 750, 
 and Hesych. in v. rpKoruXos. J. Ca- 
 pellus de Mensiir. ii. 43, finds a still 
 higher price in Pollux iv. 169, accord- 
 ing to which 3 choeis cost 4 drach- 
 mas, and consequently the metretes 
 16 drachmas; but his supposition rests 
 upon an alteration in the text, which 
 cannot be assumed. 
 
 *** Plutarch, de Anim. TmnquiL 10. 
 
 **^ IL 2, 7. The duty was laid upon 
 
 wine, corn, and other commodities at 
 half their price; but in the part where 
 the duty upon oil should be stated, 
 there is an hiatus in the text. It is 
 evident that the chus of oil, after the 
 addition of the duty, was sold for 4| 
 drachmas : but that the duty upon the 
 chus was only 3 oboli, as Camerarius 
 gives it in his translation, is an arbi- 
 trai*y assumption. The whole context 
 confirms the supposition, that a duty 
 equal to half the former price was also 
 laid upon oil. I therefore restore 
 Koi rov eXaioVj top x^^ ovra bpax^atv 
 rpifav v<0K(lv Tfrrapav koi T/)t«/3o- 
 H 2
 
 100 
 
 PRICES OF WIXE5 OIL, SALT, AND WOOD. [bK. I, 
 
 the chus of oil was sold at Lampsacus for 3 drachmas, and 
 afterwards that a duty was laid upon it equal to half its price, 
 which raised it to 4^ drachmas; consequently the metretes 
 without the duty was at 36 drachmas ; which indeed as com- 
 pared with modern prices is a low rate. 
 
 Salt, which was measured by phormi, or by medimni and 
 chcenices'*'*, was easily imported into Athens on account of 
 her dominion of the sea ; and as long as Nissea in Megaris was 
 in the hands of the Athenians, it was brought over from thence 
 with the greatest facihty^". Besides this there were salt springs 
 in Attica itself, opposite Gephyra on the other side of the 
 Cephisus, and salt-works upon the sea-shore^'^; I have not, 
 however, found anything with regard to the price of salt, except 
 that the Athenians once endeavoured to lower it by a decree of 
 the people'". 
 
 As to the supply of wood, we may observe that the Athenians 
 were forced to import large quantities of timber, particularly for 
 the uses of shiphuilding, from distant countries, especially from 
 Macedonia"*; even palisades and props for the mines were 
 brought by sea"®; small wood for burning they had in plenty, 
 particularly beech-wood, from which charcoal was made, a busi- 
 ness in which the Acharnians were chiefly engaged'®". Charcoal, 
 £rewood, and fagots were brought into the city in baskets, 
 carried either by men or on asses'®^; thus Phsenippus sent to 
 Athens every day from his boundary-estate in Cytheron six 
 asses laden with wood, which produced each day 12 drachmas'®*, 
 whence an ass's load may be estimated at 2 drachmas. 
 
 \ov, and the price in the text is given 
 according to this hypothesis. 
 
 ^* PoUux X. 169, from the Demio- 
 prata, Aristoph. Acharn. 814. [See 
 also Aristot. 11. A. viii. 10, Eiidem. 
 Eth. viii. 2. Transl.] 
 
 *'"'* Aristoph. Acharn. 760, with the 
 Scholiast and Commentators. 
 
 *5'^ See the Pirsean Inscription in 
 Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 103. [The 
 word aXfjLvpls, used in this inscription, 
 is a proper name. See Note A at the 
 
 end of book iii. Transl.] 
 
 ^'7 Aristoph. Eccles. 809, and Scho- 
 liast. 
 
 ^5« Thiicyd. iv. 108, Xenoph. HelL 
 vi. 1, 4, Demosth. in Alexand. Trtpt 
 (TvvBrjKcov p. 2 19, 4, cf. cont. Timoth. 
 p. 1192, 1, p. 1195, 1. 
 
 **^ Demosth. cont. Mid. p. 568. 
 
 '^^ Aristoph. Acharn. 
 
 *^^ Pollux vi. Ill, vii. 109. 
 
 ^^ Orat. cont. Phrenipp. p. 1041, 3.
 
 CH. XYH.] PRICES OF ARTICLES OF FOOD. 
 
 101 
 
 Chapter XVII. 
 
 The Meals of the Athenians; and the prices of Meat, Birds, 
 Fishy Vegetables, Honey, and other Articles of Food. 
 
 The meals of the Athenians, which were called fj^iKpoTpa^ 
 ire^oc, were for the most part scanty, and had little that was 
 agreeable"'. But although the ordinary fare was not very 
 expensive, the great banquets with ointments, female players 
 upon the flute and cithara, Thasian wine, eels, cheese, honey, 
 &c., were by no means cheap : ^^ they might cost,^^ says Menan- 
 der, '^a small talent/^ In the Flatterers of Eupolis a repast of 
 this kind is reckoned at 100 drachmas, and the wine at the same- 
 sum*" ; an expense sufficiently great for Athens, though small 
 in comparison with the profuseness and luxury of the kings. 
 Alexander's table for sixty or seventy persons cost 100 minas 
 a day«\ 
 
 Everything eaten, with the exception of what was prepared 
 from corn, was originally comprehended under the name of 
 Opson {oyjroy, oyjrcovcov); Plato expressly comprises under it 
 salt, olives, cheese, onions, cabbage, figs, myrtle-berries, walnuts, 
 and pulse*®^; and it is evident that roots, such as radishes, 
 turnips, &c., and all preparations of meat and fish, were also 
 included ; but by degrees the usage of this word was changed, 
 so that at length it signified only fish, the favourite food of the 
 Athenian epicures^^^ The slave in Terence buys cabbage and 
 little fish for an old man's meal at an obolus*'% but according to 
 Theophrastus''% nobody but a contemptible miser would allow 
 his wife only 3 chalcus for opson; 3 oboli appear to have been 
 sufficient for a few moderate persons to buy the opson 
 uncooked'"'; hence Lysias'^^ thinks that a guardian's charge of 
 
 ^^^ See the comic poet Antiphanes 
 ap. Athen. iv. p. 131, E, Lynceus ibid. 
 F, Alexis ibid. p. 137, D. 
 _ ^^ Pollux ix. 59. 
 
 ^«^ Athen. iv. p. 146, C. 
 
 ^«° Athen. vii. p. 277, A, Plat, de 
 Rep.ii.p. 372, C,cf. Xeuoph.CEcon.8,9. 
 
 ^^7 Athen. vii. p. 276, E. 
 ^"^ And. ii. 2, 32. 
 ^^^ Char. 28. 
 
 ^'^ Thugenides (notThucydides)j 
 Poll. vi. 38. 
 
 ^71 In Diogit. p. 905.
 
 102 PRICES OF ARTICLES OF FOOD. [bK. I. 
 
 5 obeli for the opson of two boys and a little girl was excessive. 
 Three oboli were not sufficient to procure opson for so expen- 
 sive a person as Aristippus*", and 10 drachmas appear to the 
 slave in Terence*^^ to be very inadequate for the opson of a 
 marriage-feast. The following are particular statements of 
 prices, of which, however, some are not precise. Four small 
 pieces of dressed meat cost an obolus according to Antiphanes ; 
 a piece of meat, as it was prepared for eating, probably of a 
 tolerable size, half an obolus according to Aristophanes*^\ In 
 the comic poet Aristophon*'^ a landlord appears to receive 5 
 chalcus for some small livers and an intestine, probably a 
 sausage; pverhaps the same sum from several persons who dined 
 together. A partridge, for which any other person would have 
 given an obolus, Aristippus is said to have bought for 50 
 drachmas*'* ; one extreme is as incredible as the other. A dish 
 of Boeotian fieldfares for a festival is sold for a drachma in Aris- 
 tophanes; seven thrushes, birds which in places where they are 
 abundant are usually very cheap, were not considered dear at 
 an obolus*"; and I may also mention, that in the Athenian 
 bird-market, a jackdaw was sold for 1 obolus and a crow for 3*^°. 
 Of fish Athens had a superabundance, and the smaller varie- 
 ties, which are nearly worthless in all countries that are copi- 
 ously supplied with fish, bore, as may be supposed, a very low 
 price. Membrades, a species of small fish, may be bought for 4 
 chalcus, but not eels or thunny-fish, says the comic poet Timo- 
 cles*^'; of aphuas (d(/>uat), which, according to Lucian, were 
 exceedingly small and light, a large quantity could be bought 
 for an obolus ; their cheapness is particularly mentioned. The 
 sausage-seller in Aristophanes promises to offer up a thousand 
 goats to Artemis Agrotera (outbidding in jest the offering of 
 thanks for the battle of Marathon), whenever a hundred tri- 
 chides, likewise a small kind of fish, are sold for an obolus"". 
 
 *'^'^ Diog. Laert. in Vit. Aristipp. *''' Aristoph. Adiaru. 960, Av. 1079, 
 
 with the Scholiast. 
 "•'« Aristoph. Av. 1 8. 
 ■*'' Ap. Athen. vi. p. 241, A. 
 ^^^ Lucian. Tiscat. 48 Aristoph. Eq^. 
 646, 660. 
 
 *'^ Andr. ii. 6, 20. 
 
 ''^* Antiphanes ap. Athen. iv. p. 
 431, E, Aristoph. Ran. 562. 
 *'* Pollux, iv. 70. 
 *'* Diog. Laert ubi sup.
 
 CH. XVII.] PRICES OF ARTICLES OF FOOD. 103 
 
 which was therefore an impossibility. I^arger and better fish 
 bore a higher price, and the fish-mongers were decried as a 
 shameless and avaricious race; for a sea-polype they asked 
 4 oboli, for a cestra (probably a kind of pike) 8 oboli, for two 
 cetreis [mugiles) 10 oboli, for which 8 were offered; for a sea- 
 wolf (Xd^pa^) a fishmonger asked 10 oboli, without fixing in 
 what currency ; but when it comes to payings says Diphilus, he 
 had meant ^ginetan oboli"'. A dish of echini cost, when 
 dressed, 8 oboli, according to the comic poet Lynceus"*. Eels, 
 particularly those that came from the lake Copais, were a 
 favourite dish of the Athenians, and, as well as poultry and 
 birds, were brought from BcEotia*®'. A Copaic eel cost 3 
 drachmas in the time of Aristophanes*^*. Salted or pickled 
 provisions (rdpcxos), particularly fish, were brought from the 
 Pontus, Phrygia, Egypt, Sardinia, and Cadiz*", and were very 
 abundant at Athens, in different degrees of goodness ; the com- 
 mon sorts were considered as inferior to meat, and were the 
 food of the inferior classes and of the country people, according 
 to Demosthenes and Aristophanes — as the proverb says, the 
 pickle often cost 1 obolus, but the sauce 2*^% The comic poet 
 Philippides*®' reckons a dish of pickles for one person at 2 or 3 
 oboli, and the capers for it in a separate vessel at 3 chalcus. 
 It is hardly worth mentioning that vegetables, such as cabbages, 
 &c., were sold at a cheap rate : of leguminous plants the same 
 may be concluded from an expression of Demosthenes*^, who, 
 in order to designate a time of great dearth, says, " you know 
 that even vetches were dear." Beans, which were eaten out of 
 the shells as a remedy against drunkenness, were, according to 
 the statement of Timocles, who perhaps exaggerates in joke, so 
 dear that eight pods were sold for an obolus, although they 
 
 *^^ Athen. vi. p. 224, C, to p. 227, B. : rapTvixara, Michael Apostol. xiv. 9. 
 
 *«^ Ap. Athen. iv. p. 132, B. ^«7 a p. Athen. vi. p. 230, A. At 
 
 ^' Ai-istoph. Pac. 1005, and the Rome, in the time of Cato the elder. 
 Scholiast ; also Schol. Lysist. 703. 300 denarii, or, as Polybius usually 
 Pollux vi. 63. Aristophanes in the ! says, drachmas, were given for a cask 
 Achamians. 
 
 *^^ Aristoph. Acharn. 961. 
 
 ^8* Pollux vi. 48. 
 
 *^^ 'O/ioXoO Ta.pL)(0Sy bv 6fioKa>v 
 
 of pickles from the Pontus. See Po- 
 lyb. xxxi. 24. 
 
 ^'8 Cout. Androt. p. 598, 4.
 
 104 
 
 .PRICES OF ARTICLES OF FOOD. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 always used to be sold by the cllOCllix''8^ A clicenix of olives, 
 ill the time of Socrates, sold for 2 chalcus, the cotyla of Attic, 
 that is, of the best honey, cost 5 drachmas"'^\ The warm 
 beverage which the ancients drank instead of tea, cost a chal- 
 cus, according to Philemon*^ \ 
 
 Chapter XVIII. 
 TJie Prices of Clothing, Shoes, and Ointment. 
 
 The clothing of the Athenians varied considerably in materials, 
 colour, and make, according to the time of year, as well as 
 the age, sex, family, rank, property, taste, and object of the 
 wearers ; and fashion, although not so all-powerful as in modern 
 days, had also its influence at that time. Woollen garments 
 were the most common ; although linen ones were worn, espe- 
 cially by women, and were at a low price, with the exception of 
 the finest kinds*^*. The Amorgian stuffs were an expensive 
 material, which were finer than Byssus and Carpasus, almost 
 transparent, and sometimes dyed ; they are said to have derived 
 their name from the island Amorgus, where they were best 
 manufactured ; although others derive it from the dye or the 
 plant [afjbopyr]), from which latter word the island itself pro- 
 bably received its name^^^. Even woollen garments, if the 
 
 *^^ Timocles ap. Athen. vi. p. 240, 
 E. Concerning their use see Alexis 
 ap. Poll. vi. 45j and the Commentators ; 
 and for their measure see Inscript. 
 123, ed. Boeckh. 
 
 "9" Plutarch, de Animi Tranquil. 10. 
 The expression of Aristophanes (Pac. 
 253), that the Attic honey Avas worth 
 4 oboli, must be understood proverbi- 
 ally to mean something expensive and 
 costly. See Schol. and Suid. in v. 
 T€TpoolBo\ov and reTTapcov o^oiXcov. 
 Kiister has misunderstood both pas- 
 sagos. 
 
 ^»' Ap. Poll. ix. G7, who (cap. 70) 
 correctly infers from the lowness of 
 the price, tluvt water for drinking, and 
 
 not for bathing, is meant. The words 
 of Philemon are, x'^^'^^^ depubv rjv, in 
 the reckoning of a guest with liis land- 
 lord. The preceding words in this 
 corrupt passage, koX /jLakaTpirjfiiwlBoXial, 
 earl, refer to the other articles fur- 
 nished to the guest. 
 
 •*^^ Vid. Pseudo-Plat. Epist. xiii. p. 
 3G3, A. 
 
 *^'^ They were called dixopyidia, 
 dfxopyides, Xi^rwues dfiopyivoi. See 
 concerning these, Aristoph. Lysistrat. 
 150, and Schol. Lysistrat. 736, Schol. 
 iEschin. p. 737, Reiske, Eustath. ad 
 Dionys. Perieg. Pollux vii. 57, 74. 
 Harpocrat. llesych. Suid. Etymol.
 
 CH. XVIII.] PRICES OF CLOTHING AND SHOES. l05 
 
 material and texture were of superior quality, as the Persian 
 Caunace for example''^*, were probably sold at a high price. 
 
 The prices which I have met with are as follows : Socrates, 
 as stated by Plutarch"", considers an exomis (a dress worn by 
 the common people) to be cheap when sold at Athens for 10 
 drachmas. This was a garment with one sleeve, the other arm 
 being left bare. A chlamys, the usual dress of the knights and 
 young men of Macedonian and Thessalian origin"°% is called 
 TpLCTTdrypos in Pollux"*^^, by which doubtless the weight is not 
 meant, but that its value amounted to 3 silver staters, or 12 
 drachmas. A citizen in the Ecclesiazuse of Aristophanes'*®^, 
 who appears without any upper garment, his wife having already 
 gone with it to the assembly, declares, that since the preserva- 
 tion of the state is to be the subject of debate, he himself is in 
 want of a preservation of four staters [acoTrjpla^ rerpacTTaTrjpov) ; 
 in this instance no one can doubt with Pollux"-® whether the 
 coin or the weight is meant, as it is evident that 16 drachmas, 
 the price of the upper garment, are alluded to. When the 
 young man in the Plutus^*"^ requires 20 drachmas for his aged 
 mistress for an upper garment, it is probable that he intended 
 to make her pay for an expensive one. Socrates mentions that 
 purple was sold for 3 minas, quoting it as an example of the 
 dearness of articles of luxury at Athens'*"' ; it may be doubted 
 whether by this he means a garment or a certain measure of 
 dyeing material ; in my opinion the former is the right suppo- 
 sition ; it is well known that the garments made of the Byssus 
 which grew in Achaia were weighed against gold^°^. In the 
 article of shoes great luxury was displayed ; Laconian, which 
 were the dress shoes of men, Sicyonic, Persian, Tyrrhenian, 
 Scythian, Argive, Rhodian, Amyclcean, Thessalian, and Thracian 
 shoes, with several others, occur promiscuously in the different 
 
 ^^* Aristoph. Vesp. 1132, 1140. 
 
 "95 Ubi sup. 
 
 "^^ Pollux vii. 46, X. 124, and the 
 note of Heinsterhusius, also x. 164. 
 Aramonius in v. ;(Xo/xi's and Strabo 
 ubi sup. Dorvill. ad Charit. p. 433, ed. 
 Leips. 
 
 ^^7 vi. 165. 
 
 "9« Vs. 413. 
 
 "99 ix. 58. 
 
 ^"^ Vs. 883. 
 
 ^'^^ Ap. Plutarch, ubi sup. 
 
 5"=^ PUn. Hist. Nat. xix. 4.
 
 106 
 
 PRICES OF SHOES AND OINTMENT. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 countries of Greece; and like our fashion of calling trifling 
 things after celebrated names'°% so they had various kinds of 
 shoes named after distinguished persons, such as Alcibiadean, 
 Iphicratean, Sec/"* A pair of Sicyonic women^s shoes cost 2 
 drachmas, according to Lucian*"* ; for a pair of man^s shoes the 
 above-mentioned youth in the Plutus of Aristophanes'"^ requires 
 8 drachmas, which is comparatively high, and he either asked 
 for more money than he intended to pay for the shoes, or it 
 was for some very expensive and ornamented kind. 
 
 Ointment is among the dearest articles of ancient times. 
 A cotyla of fine ointment, probably from the East, cost at 
 Athens, according to Hipparchus and Menander*"^, from 5 to 
 10 minas. The intercolutor in the comic poet Antiphanes is 
 not satisfied with moist ointment at 2 minas the cotyla'"^ It 
 is manifest that the Athenians, although they were much 
 addicted to the use of ointments, and everything contributing 
 to the refined enjoyments of life, could not have easily afforded 
 to pay so high a price. It is therefore probable that for the 
 most part they made use of inferior sorts ; of such ointment 
 perhaps as occurs in Lucian, a small alabaster box of which, 
 brought from Phoenicia, was sold for 2 drachmas*"^ 
 
 Chapter XIX. 
 
 The Prices of Household Furniture, Implements, Arms, and 
 
 Ships, 
 
 A knowledge of the prices of different kinds of furniture, 
 implements, arms, and ships, would not be unimportant for the 
 determination of many questions which it will be necessary to 
 consider. The ancient writers, however, afford but few data, 
 
 ^^ Aristophanes passim, and parti- 
 cularly Pollux vii. 85 — 89. 
 
 ^"* 'A\Kil3id8€ia or 'A\Ki^la8es 
 (Inodrjfid)^ ^IcpiKparideSy Aeividbes, 
 'S.fiivdvpidfia, MvpoKia. See Pollux 
 ubi sup. with his Commentators, 
 A then. xii. p. 534, C, Schol. Lucian. 
 Dial. ;Meretr. The Iphicratcau were 
 
 not, however, a mere variety of fashion, 
 but an improved kind of shoes for the 
 soldiers. 
 
 ^"^ Dial Meretr. 14. 
 
 ^"« Vs. 984. 
 
 *"7 Ap. Athen. xv. p.091, p. C. 
 
 *"« Ap. Atlien. ibid. 
 
 ''' Ubi sup.
 
 CH. XIX.] PRICES OF HOUSEHOLD FURNITURE, ETC. 
 
 10? 
 
 and of those which we have, some are too high to be looked 
 upon as the customary prices, although it is probable that, not- 
 withstanding the low rate of wages and the existence of slavery, 
 the manufacturers obtained a large profit, which raised the 
 price of certain commodities. 
 
 Passing over the works of art, the value of which was deter- 
 mined by the taste of the purchaser, I adduce the following 
 examples. A little cart for a child's plaything cost an obolus, 
 according to Aristophanes, and a small oil-flask {XrjKvOvov) the 
 same sum, an earthen cask 3 drachmas'^" ; a sideboard {iyyvOi]Ki]) 
 decorated with brazen figures of satyrs and heads of oxen*'', 
 not particularly well executed, 30 drachmas ; a small two- 
 wheeled chariot for racing, probably with many ornaments 
 of ivory, brass, silver, &c., in the same manner that the 
 ancients used them upon beds and other kinds of furniture* ^% 
 together with the wheels, cost 3 minas*'\ The price of a scythe 
 or sickle {Bpiiravov) in time of peace is evidently exaggerated 
 in joke by Aristophanes'^*, who supposes 50 drachmas to be 
 given for it. A private key together with the ring cost in the 
 same age 3 oboli, a magic ring a drachma' '*. A small book for 
 an agreement (ypafi/jbaTiBcov), i. e, a small ordinary wooden 
 diptychon with two wax tablets, Demosthenes values at 2 
 chalcus''^ The assize price of a rope, such as a man might use 
 for hanging himself, was an obolus'^'. Arms and armour can- 
 not have been cheap ; in the time of war, when the demand 
 was considerable, 10 minas were, according to Aristophanes, 
 (who probably mentions the highest rate,) the price of a coat 
 of mail of good workmanship and fastened with metal chains 
 {aXvacBcjTos); 1 mina, as it appears, for a helmet; and 60 
 drachmas for a war-trumpet'^^. 
 
 For determining the expenses of the marine it would be 
 
 ^'" Aristoph. Nub. 861, Ran. 1267, 
 Pac. 1201. 
 
 *" Lysias Fragm. p. 15. 
 
 **** Plutarch, de vitando oere alieno, 
 2,3. 
 
 *" Aristoph. Nub. 31. 
 
 ^i* Pac. 1200. 
 
 5'* Aristoph. Thesm. 432, Plut. 885. 
 
 •■''^ Demosth. cont. Dionysod. p. 1283, 
 4, cf. Sahnas. de M. U. X. p. 403. 
 
 5^7 Lucian. Timon. 20. 
 
 *'» Aristoph. Pac. 1223, and the 
 Schol. 1250 and 1240.
 
 IDS PRICES OF SHIPS. [bK. I. 
 
 particularly desirable to know the prices of articles employed 
 in ship-building, but little definite information can be gathered 
 from the passages of ancient writers. A piece of wood for 
 making an oar {KcoTrevs) cost, according to Andocides'^% 5 
 drachmas ; Lucian, who both from the lateness of the period 
 at which he lived and the bent of his writings cannot be suffi- 
 cient evidence, supposes the fraudulent god Hermes in a 
 reckoning with Charon to ask the moderate sum of 5 drachmas 
 for an anchor for Charon's boat, which to the covetous ferryman 
 appears a large sum ; for the thong with which the oar was 
 fastened on {rpoTrcortjp), 2 oboli ; for a needle to sew toge- 
 ther the sail cloth, 5 oboli ; for pitching-wax, nails, and cords 
 for the sail-yard, altogether 2 drachmas. 
 
 The cost of a whole ship as compared with its size 
 cannot now be ascertained. In a bottomry bond in Demos- 
 thenes"", 3000 drachmas are lent upon a merchant-vessel, by 
 which however we are not justified in assuming that the ship 
 had not a greater value, as at Athens a double pledge was not 
 unfrequently given in case of bottomry, and therefore its real 
 value might have been as much as a talent. Nor could the cost 
 of a trireme or the common ship of war, without its furniture, 
 have been much greater, as labour could be procured at a low 
 rate, and ships were easily built ; for which reason they did not 
 last long, but were frequently wrecked when out at sea, and. 
 were shattered to pieces in battle. A calculation has been 
 made from accounts of the expenses of the trierarchy, that it 
 cost a talent to build the hull of a trireme, but it is founded 
 upon an erroneous supposition ; another means of determining 
 the price might have been derived from the account of Themis- 
 tocles having built 100 or 200 triremes from the annual pro- 
 ceeds of the mines ; but neither can the annual returns of the 
 mines nor the number of years be ascertained with certainty : 
 the statement of Polysenus that a ship was built for every talent 
 which was allowed, is after all the most pro])able"' ; but it was 
 
 *'^ De suo Reditu, p. 81. The next ' Klines of Laurion. According to Di- 
 passage is Lucian. Dial. Mort. 4. ; odorus (see below, b. ii. ch. 20), there 
 
 *^ Cont. Dionysod. p. 1283, 18. 
 *-' See my Dissertation upon the 
 
 were perhaps twenty triremes built 
 every year.
 
 CH. XIX.] PRICES OF SHIPS. 109 
 
 perhaps only a contribution granted to the trierarchs, who 
 according to the most ancient form of the trierarchy were 
 obliged to supply all the furniture of the vessel, and were only 
 to be indemnified for the building of the hull. Subsequently, 
 however, on account of the general rise of prices, a trireme may 
 have stood a little higher : would that instead of the fictitious 
 sale of the triremes for 15 drachmas, at which the Corinthians 
 once furnished some vessels to the Athenians'", we had a 
 statement of their real value ! 
 
 Chapter XX. 
 
 On the Sum necessary for the Support of a Family in Attica, and 
 its relation to the National Wealth, 
 
 From the preceding particulars, it is possible very nearly to 
 determine the sum which was requisite for the maintenance of 
 a respectable person in the best times of Athens. The most 
 moderate person required every day for opson 1 obolus, for a 
 choenix of corn, according to the price of barley in the age of 
 Socrates, a quarter obolus, making altogether in a year of 360 
 days, 75 drachmas; and for clothes and shoes at least 15 
 drachmas ; a family of four adults must therefore at the lowest 
 have required 360 drachmas for the specified necessaries; 
 which sum for the age of Demosthenes, when the price of corn 
 was 5 drachmas, must be increased by 22^ drachmas for each 
 person, and for four persons by 90: to this the expense of 
 house-room is to be added, which, if we reckon the value of a 
 house at the lowest at 3 minas, taking the ordinary rate of 
 interest of 12 per cent., gives an outlay of 36 drachmas; so 
 that the poorest family of four free adults spent upon an 
 average from 390 to 400 drachmas a year, if they did not live 
 upon bread and water. 
 
 Socrates had two wives, not indeed at the same time, as has 
 been fabulously reported, but one after the other; the first was 
 Myrto, whom he married poor, and probably without a dowry; 
 
 Herod, vi. 89.
 
 110 
 
 THE SUM NECESSARY FOR 
 
 [bk. r. 
 
 the second Xanthippe ; he had three children, of whom Lam- 
 procles at the death of his father had reached the age of 
 manhood, while Sophroniscus and Menexenus were minors**'; 
 for himself, after having sacrificed his youth to unceasing 
 endeavours after knowledge, he followed no profession, and 
 his teaching did not produce any pecuniary return. According 
 to Xenophon"*, he lived upon his own property, which if it 
 had found a good purchaser {ot)vrjTr)si), would, together with the 
 house, have readily produced 5 minas; and he only required 
 a small contribution from his friends : whence it has been 
 inferred that prices were extraordinarily low at Athens. It is, 
 however, evident that Socrates and his family could not have 
 lived upon the proceeds of so small a property ; for, however 
 miserable his house may have been, it cannot be estimated at 
 less than 3 minas, so that even if the furniture is not taken 
 into consideration, the rest of his effects only amounted to 2 
 minas, and the income from them, according to the ordinary 
 rate of interest, was only 24 drachmas, from which he could not 
 have provided barley for himself and his wife, not to mention 
 the other necessaries of life and the maintenance of his 
 children. 
 
 Shall we then understand the expression " purchaser 
 [wvTjTT]^),'' to mean a lessee of his property, and 5 minas to be 
 the annual rent? This way of avoiding the difficulty would 
 be the easiest ; but the ancients, as far as I am aware, only use 
 the word " to buy (oovelo-daty instead of " to let,^' as applied 
 to the public revenues, the letting of which was a real sale of 
 the dues belonging to the state ; for a lease of the lands or the 
 whole property (oIkos) of an individual to a tenant, the expres- 
 sion /jLLadovv is used; and, moreover, a lease of the whole 
 property never occurs, as far as I am aware, except in the case 
 of the estates of orphans. 
 
 In addition to this, the fortune of Critobulus is valued at 
 more than 500 minas, in the same sense as that of Socrates is 
 at 5, with the remark that he reduced his means, as he offered 
 
 5*3 Plat. Apol. 23, and there Fischer. 
 
 '-•* CEcon. 2. According to Meur- 
 
 sius, who has been transcribed by later 
 
 writere, he lived upon it very respect- 
 ably (per honeste) ! See Fort. Att. 
 iv. p. 30.
 
 CH. XX.] THE SUPPORT OF A FAMILY. Ill 
 
 munificent sacrifices, entertained guests, feasted and main- 
 tained many citizens, kept horses, performed public liturgies, 
 and subjected himself to other expenses besides the mainte- 
 nance of his wife, things which, with an income of 8^ talents, he 
 would have been undoubtedly able to afford, but not with only 
 a property of that value. We must therefore believe that 
 Xenophon stated the whole property of Socrates at only 5 
 minas, but we have equal right to reject as to receive this 
 testimony; for the history of the ancient philosophers is so 
 corrupted and mixed with fables, and the circumstances of 
 their lives have been so differently represented even by con- 
 temporary writers, that one seldom treads upon firm ground. 
 Thus in the Apology of Plato, Socrates is represented as saying 
 that he need not have given more than a mina of silver for his 
 release ; in which account Eubulides also agreed : according to 
 others he estimated the whole cause at 25 drachmas; and in 
 the Apology for Socrates attributed to Xenophon, it is related 
 that he had neither valued his law-suit himself, nor would 
 allow it to be valued by his friends^" ! Thus the well-informed 
 Demetrius of Phalerum maintained, in opposition to Xenophon, 
 that Socrates had, besides his house, 70 minas lent out to 
 Criton upon interest; and Libanius relates that he had lost 
 80 minas, which were left him by his father, through a friend 
 who had failed in his business, whom we can by no means 
 suppose with Schneider to have been the wealthy Crito"^. 
 
 But assuming Xenophon's account to be entirely correct, it 
 must be thought that the mother of the young sons maintained 
 herself and two children either by her labour or out of her 
 dowry, while Lamprocles supported himself, and that the 
 domestic economy for which Socrates was so celebrated, con- 
 sisted in keeping his family at work. He may in that case, 
 indeed, have lived upon his 24 drachmas, together with some 
 additional contributions from his friends ; for his necessary 
 expenses were exceedingly small, and no one could live as he 
 
 ^'^ Plat. Apol. 28 ; Diog. Laeit. ii. 
 41; Xenoph. Apol. 23. 
 
 '-•^ Demetrius ap.Plutai-cb.Aristid.l, , 
 where ttjv oiKiav should resume its place | 
 
 iu the text for Reiske's yijf oiKeiav; Li- 
 ban. Apol. vol. iii. p. 7 ; Schneider ad 
 Xenoph. ubi sup.
 
 112 
 
 THE SUM NECESSARY FOR 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 did. It is true that he is related to have often sacrificed at 
 home and upon the pubUc altars"^, but doubtless only baked 
 animals, according to the custom of the poor, or properly- 
 speaking, loaves of bread, which were chiefly consumed with 
 the meat, and to which his family also contributed ; he lived in 
 the strictest sense upon bread and water, except when he was 
 entertained by his friends ; and therefore he may have been much 
 rejoiced, as he is said to have been, at barley being sold at the 
 low price of a quarter obolus the choenix^^^ : he wore no under- 
 garment; and his upper-garment was slight, the same for 
 summer and winter ; he generally went bare-footed, and his 
 dress-shoes which he sometimes wore, probably lasted him his 
 whole life. A walk before his house served him instead of 
 opson for meals ; in short no slave lived so poorly as he did*'^ 
 His greatest expense was unquestionably the drachma which 
 he gave to Prodicus; and without disparaging the greatness 
 of his intellectual powers, it may be boldly asserted, that as far 
 as his miserable condition and a certain resemblance to the 
 habits of the Cynic philosophers are concerned, the repre- 
 sentation of Aristophanes is not only not exaggerated, but is 
 faithfully copied after the life. 
 
 Jf in the time of Socrates four persons could live upon 440 
 drachmas a year, they must have passed a very wretched 
 existence, and to live respectably it was necessary even then, 
 and still more in the time of Demosthenes, to be possessed of a 
 larger income. According to the Speech against Pheenippus, 
 the plaintiff and his brother inherited from their father 45 
 minas each, upon which the orator says it was not easy to 
 live'^", that is upon the interest, which, according to the com- 
 mon rate, amounts to 540 drachmas. Isseus in his speech 
 upon the estate of Hagnias"^ relates, that Stratocles and his 
 
 *^^ Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. init. 
 
 ^^^ See Plutarch and Stobaeus in the 
 passages quoted m chap. 15. 
 
 =*'^ Xenoph. ut sup. i. 5, 2 ; Plat. 
 Conviv. p. 174, A; Athen. iv. p. 157, E. 
 Many pei-sons used to go barefooted, 
 even the wealthy and distinguislied 
 
 Lycurgus. (See Lives of the Ten 
 Orators.) 
 
 ^ ' ' P. 292, where read eivai fiev Uava^ 
 Xetrovpyeii/ 5f fxr) <i^ia, as Reiske pro- 
 posed, with tlie addition however of 
 another unhappy conjecture. Ol';^ ikuvo.
 
 CH. XX.] THE SUPPORT OF A FAMILY. 113 
 
 brother had inherited an estate from their father, which was 
 indeed too inconsiderable to oblige them to the performance of 
 liturgies, but sufficient for their maintenance : now since the 
 property of Statocles amounted at his death to 5^ talents, 
 besides his wife^s dowry of 20 minas, which cannot be 
 reckoned into his legacy, and since out of this sum he had 
 acquired either by subsequent inheritance or his own exertions 
 the sum of 4 talents 44 minas, his patrimony amounted to 
 46 minas, which according to the ordinary rate of interest 
 afforded an income of 5 minas 52 drachmas a year, and at the 
 rate of 18 per cent, at which he lent it out, 8 minas 28 drachmas, 
 and with the interest of the dowry reckoned at 12 per cent. 
 10 minas 68 drachmas, an income which was amply sufficient 
 to maintain him. 
 
 Mantitheus, in a speech of Demosthenes*^^ asserts that he 
 had been supported and educated from the interest of his 
 mother's dowry, which amounted to a talent, consequently, 
 according o the customary rate of interest, from 720 drachmas. 
 The expenses of Demosthenes himself when a youth, of his 
 young sister, and of his mother, amounted to 7 minas a year, 
 exclusively of the cost of house-rent, as they lived in their own 
 house : but the cost of Demosthenes' education was not paid 
 out of this sum, as it remained owing by the guardians"^ After 
 Lysias had finished speaking of the fraudulent account rendered 
 by the guardian of Diodotus' children, (who for example had 
 charged more than a talent for clothes, shoes, and hair-cutting, 
 within eight years, and more than 4000 drachmas for sacrifices 
 and festivals, and at the termination of his office would only 
 surrender 2 minas of silver and 30 Cyzicenic staters)"*, he 
 remarks"', that " if he charges more than any person in the 
 city ever did for two boys and a girl, a nurse and female 
 
 is manifestly corrupt, in the first place 
 because it ought to be fit), and not ov, 
 and in the second, because it would 
 be absurd to remark, that his property 
 was iiuleed not sufficient to live upon, 
 but too inconsiderable for the per- 
 formance of liturgies. 
 
 ^^2 Cont. Bceot. de Dote, p. 1009, 
 28 ; p. 1023, G. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. cont. Aphob. i. p. 824, 
 26 sqq. p. 828, 5. 
 
 53* Cont. Diogit. p. 903, cf. p. 897, 
 and p. 905. 
 
 "' Ibid. p. 910. 
 
 I
 
 114 THE SUM NECESSARY FOR [bK. 1. 
 
 servant, he could not reckon more than 1000 drachmas a year;" 
 which would give not much less than 3 drachmas a day. This 
 is equal to nearly 2s, 6d. in English money, a sum which cer- 
 tainly must appear too large for three children and two female 
 slaves in the time of Lysias. 
 
 In the age of Solon an obolus must have gone very far, for 
 that legislator prohibited any woman from carrying with her 
 upon any procession or journey more than would buy thus 
 much of food, together with a basket which was more than an 
 ell long"® : and the Troezenians appear to have made a liberal 
 donation, when, according to Plutarch"^, they decreed to allow 
 2 oboh to every one of the old men, women, and children, who 
 had fled from Athens at the time of the invasion of Xerxes. 
 But in the flourishing times of the state, one person could live 
 but moderately upon 2 or even 3 oboU a day"^; upon the 
 whole, the cheapness and facility of living were considerable. 
 From the piety of the Greeks towards the dead, the death of a 
 man, with his funeral and monument, often cost more than 
 many years of his life, for we find that private individuals 
 frequently spent for that purpose as much as 3, 10, 50, or even 
 120 minas"^ 
 
 The aggregate wealth of the Athenian people, exclusive of 
 the public property and the mines, I have estimated in a 
 succeeding part of this work, upon a probable calculation, at 
 from 30,000 to 40,000 talents"*"; if of this sum only 20,000 
 talents are reckoned as property paying interest, each of the 
 20,000 citizens would have had the interest of a talent, or, 
 according to the ordinary rate of interest, an annual income of 
 
 "« Plutarch. Solon. 21. 
 
 "V Themistocl. 10. 
 
 ^^^ Lucian (Epist. Saturn. 21) says, 
 
 author (Dial. IMort. 7). This how- 
 ever cannot be applied to Athens 
 and to ancient times, without modiii- 
 
 that in order to satiate one's self with cations. 
 
 wheat or barley bread, together with j *^^ Lysias cont. Philon. p. 884; 
 a few cresses, some thyme, or a few j Pseudo-Plat, Epist. xiii. p. 3GI, E; 
 onions, 4 oboli Avere wanting ; which Demosth. c. Boeot, de Dote, p. 1023, 
 is the very sum that a miserly father 22 ; Lysias. c. Diogit. p. 905 ; De- 
 gives to his son who has reached his mosth. c. Stephan. i. p. 1124, 15. 
 eighteenth year, for his daily suste- | ^*^ Book iv. ch. 4. 
 nance, in another place in the same i
 
 GH. XX.] THE SUPPORT OF A FAMILY. 115 
 
 720 drachmas, if property had been equally divided, which the 
 ancient philosophers and statesmen always considered as the 
 greatest good fortune of a state ; and with the addition of the 
 produce of their labour, they might have been all able to live 
 comfortably. But a considerable number of the citizens were 
 poor; while others were possessed of great riches, who from 
 the lowness of prices and the high rate of interest w^ere able not 
 only to live luxuriously, but at the same time to accumulate 
 additional wealth, as capital increased with extreme rapidity. 
 
 This inequality destroyed the State and the morals of the 
 inhabitants. The most natural consequence of it was the ser- 
 vility of the poor towards the rich, although they thought that 
 they had the same pretensions as their superiors in wealth; 
 and the w^ealthy citizens practised the same canvassing for 
 popular favour, as was the custom at Rome, with different 
 degrees of utility, or rather of hurtfulness. A citizen might 
 perhaps adopt beneficial means for obtaining his end, as Cimon 
 for example, the first man of his age, who, besides his great 
 mental qualities, imitated Pisistratus in leaving his lands and 
 gardens without any keepers, and thus the produce of his farms 
 and his house became almost the property of the public ; he 
 used also to provide cheap entertainments for the poor, to bury 
 the indigent, to distribute small pieces of money when he went 
 out, and to cause his attendants to change clothes wdth decayed 
 citizens^^^ Yet these were the very means by which the sove- 
 reign citizens were reduced to a miserable state of beggary and 
 dependance. 
 
 Even this, however, might have been tolerable ; but as every 
 statesman had not the means of making such large outlays from 
 his private fortune, and liberality to the people being necessary 
 to purchase their favour, the distribution of money at the 
 festivals, the payment of the soldiers, ecclesiasts, dicasts, and 
 senators, the costly sacrifices, and the cleruchise, were intro- 
 duced by the demagogues : the allies were compelled to try 
 their causes at Athens, among other reasons for producing more 
 
 ^*^ Theopomp. ap. Athen. xii. p. 533, A; Plutai'cb Cimon. 10, partly from 
 Aristotle, and Pericl. 9. 
 
 42
 
 116 THE SUM FOR SUPPORT OF A FAMILY. [bK. I. 
 
 fees to the dicasts, and employment for the other citizens**': 
 every description of oppressive acts against the allies, and public 
 crimes were the consequence, which the demagogues pretended 
 that they were driven to by the poverty of the people^*\ And 
 when the necessary consequence and punishment of their 
 tyranny arrived in the defection of the allies, the helpless con- 
 dition of the state had increased ; for the multitude had forgotten 
 their former activity, and been gradually accustomed to ease 
 and refinement ; no course therefore remained but to struggle 
 to regain their former ascendancy. Add to this the envy which 
 the poor entertained against the rich, and the joy and readiness 
 with which they divided their possessions, upon which, after 
 bribery had been tried in vain, the whole rage of the multitude 
 vented itself. Xenophon, in his Treatise upon the Revenues, 
 understood perfectly that it was necessary to promote the 
 welfare of individuals: but, leaving out of the question the 
 insufficiency of his proposals, Athens, if her wealth and power 
 could have been restored, was lost beyond all hope of recovery, 
 as the minds of her citizens could not be so easily recalled to a 
 state consistent with her desired prosperity. 
 
 Chapter XXI. 
 Wages of Labour in Attica. 
 
 From the extreme cheapness of the necessaries of life, the 
 wages of labour must have been at a low rate in ancient times ; 
 and the number of competitors in the market for labour, among 
 whom, besides the Thetes and the resident aliens, a large por- 
 tion of slaves should be reckoned, must have contributed to 
 produce a farther diminution*"**. In addition to the effect of 
 competition, the gangs of slaves maintained by the wefalthy 
 essentially injured the profits of the poorer classes of citizens. 
 And it was with justice that the Phocians, who are said to have 
 formerly prohibited the keeping of slaves, upbraided Mnason, 
 
 ">'■' Xenoph. de Rep. Athen. ^^^ Xenoph. de Vectig. init. 
 
 Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 
 
 544
 
 CH. XXI.] WAGES OF LABOUR. 117 
 
 who possessed more than a thousand, with keeping an equal 
 number of citizens out of employment'". After the Pelopon- 
 nesian war, even citizens who had been accustomed to live in a 
 better condition of life — however repugnant it was to their 
 feelings — were compelled to maintain themselves by working for 
 daily wages at any manual labour, as they had lost their foreign 
 estates, rents had fallen as well from the scarcity of money, as 
 from the decrease of the population, and loans were not to be 
 procured^^^ 
 
 I have been able to find but few exact statements of the 
 amount of wages of labour : Lucian states, that in the age of 
 Timon (provided he does not refer to earlier what really 
 belongs to later times) 4 oboli were the daily wages for garden 
 or field-labour upon a distant estate'**'^; this same sum occurs 
 as a porter's wages in Aristophanes, and of a common labourer 
 who carried manure'*^ When Ptolemy sent 100 masons and 
 350 labourers to the Rhodians, in order to repair the damage 
 caused by the earthquake, he gave them 14 talents a year for 
 opson, that is, 3 oboli a-piece^''^; which, if they were slaves, was 
 the expense of their maintenance, if free labourers, only a part 
 of their wages, as a man required other things besides opson. 
 The philosophers Menedemus and Asclepiades must have been 
 powerful labourers in their youth, if they earned 2 drachmas a 
 night for grinding in a corn milP^°. Particular services, which 
 require a certain degree of compliance on the part of the 
 labourers, received a higher recompense at Athens, as in all 
 other cities. Bacchus, in the Frogs of Aristophanes"', wishes 
 to have his bundle carried by a porter, who asks 2 drachmas 
 for his trouble; but when the god offers the departed shade 9 
 oboli, he declares that " rather than do this he would return to 
 life again.'' If this dialogue in the region of shades is not a 
 scene of real life, it has no point : a living porter at Athens 
 would be equally exorbitant in his demands, and if less was 
 
 549 
 
 5-^ Atlien. vi. p. 264, C. cf. p. 272, B 
 ^'^ Xenopli. Mem. Socrat. ii. 7, 8. 
 ^■•7 Liician. Timon. 6, 12. 
 ''^ Aristoph. ap. Poll. vii. 133, and j ''' Vs. 172 sqq 
 Eccles. 310. 
 
 Polyb. V. 88. 
 ^^^ Phanodemiis and Fhilochorus 
 ap. Athen. iv. p. 1G8, A.
 
 118 WAGES OF LABOUR. [bK. I. 
 
 offered him, he might naturally answer that he would sooner 
 die than do it. 
 
 The fare paid for passages by sea was extremely moderate, 
 particularly for long voyages ; it cost 2 oboli to go from ^Egina 
 to the Piraeus; that is, for more than 21 miles; the fare from 
 Egypt or the Pontus to the same port, more than 600 miles, 
 for a man with his family and baggage, was at most 2 drachmas 
 in the age of Plato; a proof that commerce was very profitable, 
 so that it was not found necessary to require much from pas- 
 sengers. In the time of Lucian the fare from Athens to ^gina 
 was 4 oboli"^ The freight of timber appears to have been 
 more considerable in a case mentioned by Demosthenes*^, in 
 which 1 750 drachmas were paid for a cargo from Macedonia to 
 Athens : the immense corn vessel the Isis, which, in the time 
 of the emperors, brought so much corn from Egypt to Italy, 
 that it was asserted that one cargo would be sufficient for a 
 year's consumption of all Attica, produced at the least 12 talents 
 of freightage per annum'^*"'. 
 
 The fulling of an upper garment cost 3 oboli^". 30 drachmas 
 were paid for engraving a decree of moderate size, if we may 
 judge from the fragment that remains; 50 drachmas were 
 assigned for engraving all the decrees of Lycurgus in the 
 archonship of Anaxicrates (Olymp. 118, 2, B.C. 307)"% which 
 can only be explained by supposing that the writing was for 
 the most part very small. The great inscription which was 
 first published by Barthelemy"^ is only 3' 8'^ 4'^^ Paris mea- 
 sure high, 6" Q" thick, the upper part, which contains an image 
 in high relief, is 1' 11'% the lower part, upon which the writing 
 is engraved, 2' 4'^ 6'^" wide. The whole inscription consists of 
 only 40 rows of letters, which are 3i lines high, with spaces 
 between the rows of 2 lines in height ; so that the whole height 
 
 =** Plat. Gorg. § 143, ed. Heiiidorf. | "^ Aristoplu Vesp. 1123, cf. 1122.' 
 Luciau. vol. iii. p. 258, ed Reiz. i ^^^ Mann. Oxon. xxiv. ed. ChandL 
 
 "^ Cont. Timoth. p. 1192. That ; and in some unpublished inscriptions ; 
 only one cargo is meant is evident third decree at the end of the Lives, 
 from tlie mention of only one cap- of the Ten Orators, 
 tain, Ibid. 1, 24. i "7 xhe Choiseul inscription. 
 
 •^* Lucian ut sup. p. -5(J. 1
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 WAGES OF LABOUR. 
 
 119 
 
 of the inscription itself is 1' 6'' 4''". In addition to this we may- 
 notice the payments at the baths, which, according to Lucian, 
 amounted to 2 oboli, although they cannot be considered solely 
 as the wages of labour"'. For the labour of plucking out the 
 hair with pitch, in order to make the skin resemble that of a 
 woman, a fashionable gentleman is represented in Philemon as 
 paying four men 6 chalcus a-piece, as it appears from a passage 
 in Pollux"^ It may be also observed the rich had private^ 
 and the people of Athens public baths'^**. 
 
 The pay of the soldiers was different according to times 
 and circumstances, and varied between 2 oboli and 2 drach- 
 mas, the latter including the provision-money for an hoplite 
 and his attendant ; the cavalry received from two to four times, 
 officers generally twice, and generals only four times that 
 amount: the provision-money w^as usually equal to the pay* 
 A soldier could maintain himself sufficiently well for 2 or 
 3 oboli, especially as in many places living was much 
 cheaper than at Athens; out of his pay he was to provide 
 clothes and arms, after which a certain surplus remained, which^ 
 if he had opportunities to plunder, might enable him to amass 
 a decent fortune. This explains the meaning of the comic poet 
 Theopompus^", who says," that with a pay of 2 oboli a soldier 
 could maintain a wife, and with 4 oboli his fortune was com- 
 plete ; where he means the pay alone without the provision. 
 
 The pay of the dicasts and ecclesiasts amounted in its 
 increased state to 3 oboli, and like the theorica, only served 
 as a contribution to the support of the citizens : the Heliast in 
 the Wasps of Aristophanes^^^ clearly shows the difficulty which 
 there was in procuring bread, opson, and wood, for three per- 
 
 5^^ Lexiphanes, 2. 
 
 ^^^ ix. 66, and there Hemsterhuis. 
 The operation takes place at the bath. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 2, 10; see 
 Barthe'l. Anach. torn. ii. chap. 20. 
 
 ^®' Ap. Poll. ix. 64, where read with 
 KUhn, 
 
 KaiVot ris ovk av cIkos €v npaTTOi 
 T€Tpa>l3oXi^oiv, 
 
 El vvv ye Stco/SoXoi/ (f)ep<i}v dvfjp Tpe(f)€i 
 yvvaiKa. 
 [Porson Prref. Eurip. Hec. p. 43, 
 writes the last line, et vvv y dvrjp 
 8ia)^o\ov (pepet rp€<ji€Lv yvvaiKa. The 
 correct reading probably is, et vvv y 
 dvrjp 8i(aj3o\ov (f)ep(ov Tpe<pei yvvaiKa. 
 Transl.] 
 
 56^ Vesp. 299, cf. 699.
 
 120 WAGES OF LABOUR. [bK. !• 
 
 sons out "ftf this allowance : clothes and house-room he does 
 not reckon^ as these he provided from his private property. 
 The salaries of the senators and ambassadors were more consi- 
 derable; the liberal arts and sciences were the most abundantly- 
 paid, although the remmieration of the courtesans was scarcely 
 inferior. 
 
 The ancient states maintained physicians who were paid at 
 the public cost^^^; thus, for example, Hippocrates is said to 
 have been public physician at Athens : these again had attend- 
 ants, for the most part slaves, who exercised their calling among 
 people of low condition'"'. The celebrated physician Democedes 
 of Croton received about the sixtieth Olympiad, (540 b. c.,) 
 notwithstanding the small quantity of money then in circulation, 
 the large salary of 36 ^Eginetan minas or of 1 Attic talent 
 of silver : being invited to Athens, he received 100 minas, 
 until Polycrates of Samos gave him 2 talents'". It cannot be 
 doubted that many artists of a different description w^ere paid 
 in a similar manner by the state, such as the architects at 
 Rhodes and Cyzicus, and doubtless at every place of impor- 
 tance. 
 
 The pay of musicians and actors w^as very considerable. 
 Amoebeus, a singer in ancient Athens, received an Attic talent 
 for each time that he appeared'"" : it is well known that the 
 flute payers were very highly paid. In a Corcyrsean inscrip- 
 tion'"^ of no great antiquity, 50 Corinthian, or 83^ Attic minas, 
 are fixed as the pay for three auletae, three tragic, and three 
 comic actors for a festivity, besides the large expenses of their 
 maintenance. Distinguished actors were not less highly paid, 
 although they made great additional gains by travelling from 
 place to place, when they were not employed at Athens'"^; 
 thus, for example, Polus or Aristodemus is said to have gained 
 a talent in two davs, or even in one'"". In like manner com- 
 
 ^°^ Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. iv. 2, 5, i ^'^^ Inscript. 150, ed. Boeckli. 
 Plat. Gorg. § 23. Concerning tlie ^'^^ Cf. Deniostli. de Fals. Leg. and 
 pay see Strab. iv. p. 125, Diod. xii. 13. the second argument to this oration. 
 
 '■' Plat. Leg. ^°» Vit. X. Orat. p. 268, ed. Tubing. 
 
 ■■^'^ Herod, iii. i:Jl. Gell. xi. 9, 10. Concerning the pay of 
 
 ''"' Aristcas ap. Athen. xv. p.(>23, D. ; tiic common actora at Rome, see Lip-
 
 CII. XXI.] 
 
 WAGES OF LABOUR. 
 
 121 
 
 mon strolling players, jugglers, conjurors, fortune-tellers, &c., 
 gained a competence by their callings, although the sum which 
 one person paid was inconsiderable ; for example, a chalcus, an 
 obolus, though sometimes as much as a drachma""; appren- 
 tices' fees for instruction in trades and arts, including even that 
 of medicine, had been introduced in the time of Socrates"^ 
 The tribes at Athens were bound to provide for a part of the 
 instruction in music and gymnastic exercises, and they had 
 their own teachers, by whom the youth of the whole tribe were 
 instructed""*; in the other schools each person paid, but how 
 much we are not informed"^: an exception was made to this 
 rule by some enactments of Charondas, who is said to have 
 appointed salaries for the grammarians, if the laws, from which 
 Diodorus"** took his account, are not fabrications. 
 
 The teachers of philosophy and rhetoric, or the sophists, 
 were not paid by the state till later times ; at first, however, 
 they obtained large sums from their scholars, the worthy suc- 
 cessors of the mercenary lyric poets, whose inspiration was fre- 
 quently the result of gold"\ Protagoras of Abdera is said to 
 have been the first who taught for money, and he received from 
 a pupil 100 minas for his complete education''^; Gorgias"' 
 required the same sum, notwithstanding which he only left at 
 his death 1000 staters"'; together with Zeno of Elea"', who 
 
 sins Exc. N. ad Tacit. Annal. 1. It 
 is difficult to believe that Demosthenes 
 gave 10,000 drachmas to the actor 
 Neoptolemus for teaching him to speak 
 with long breath, as is stated in the 
 lives of the Ten Orators, p. 2G0. 
 
 ^70 Casanb. ad Theophrast. Char. 6. 
 Lucian gives a good deal of infonnatiou 
 with regard to the fortune-tellers : the 
 most remarkable instance of growing 
 rich by this art occurs in Isocrat. 
 ^ginet. 
 
 =^^ Plat. Menon. p. 90, B. sqq. 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. cont. Boeot. de Nom. 
 p. 1001, 19. 
 
 ••7* Demosth. cont. Aphob. i. p. 82f?. 
 
 '"''■^ Diod. xii. 13. Although their 
 spuriousness has been proved, yet 
 
 every thing that occui-s in them cannot 
 be rejected as forged; the latter law, 
 however, gives strong gi-ounds for sus- 
 pecting that it is of the Alexandrian 
 age. 
 
 ^^^ Many persons have treated of 
 the pay of learned men. The most 
 important particulars have been col- 
 lected by Wolf ( Vermischte Schriften, 
 p. 42, sqq.), without any parade of 
 quotations. [See also Smith's Wealtli 
 of Nations, b. 1, ch. 10. Tbansl.] 
 
 576 Quintil. Inst. Orat. iii. 1, Gell. 
 V. 10, Diog. ix. 52, and there ^Menage. 
 
 ^77 Suidas, and Diod. xii. 53. 
 
 5'^ Isocrat. de Antidosi, § 16'7, ed. 
 Bckker. 
 
 "'^ riat. Alcib. i. p. 119, A. The
 
 122 WAGES OF LABOUR. [bK. I. 
 
 was otherwise unlike the sophists. Instruction being obtained 
 at so high a price^ it is natural that persons should have bar- 
 gained and endeavoured to agree for moderate terms ; at which 
 we who carry on the same trade with books, as they with their 
 oral instruction, should be the last to be astonished, Hippias, 
 while still a young man, together with Protagoras, earned in 
 Sicily, in a very short space of time, 150 minas, of which more 
 than 20 minas came from one small town; and not, as it 
 appears, by any long course of education^^". By degrees, how- 
 ever, the number of teachers brought about a reduction of the 
 price : Euenus of Paros, as early as in the time of Socrates, 
 exposed himself to the ridicule of the multitude by taking only 
 10 minas^^', for which sum, also, Isocrates taught the whole art 
 of rhetoric*^'^ ; and this in the time of Lycurgus was considered 
 as the common remuneration of a teacher of eloquence^^^ At 
 last even the followers of Socrates were content to teach for 
 money, Aristippus having, as it is said, been the first to set the 
 example^^*. It may be also mentioned, that they used to 
 receive money from each pupil for private lectures ; thus Pro- 
 dicus received from 1, 2, and 4, to 50 drachmas*^*. Antiphon 
 was the first person who wrote speeches for money, and he was 
 paid highly for them^^^. 
 
 I am almost ashamed to speak of the prices of intercourse 
 with persons of both sexes, which, according to Suidas and 
 Zonaras^^^, were fixed by law : 3 chalcus, 1 and 2 oboli, a 
 
 Scholiast of Aristophanes (Nub. 873) 
 states that the teachers would not 
 have readily taken less than a talent : 
 if any reliance is to be placed on this 
 account, which is hardly necessary, it 
 
 Orat. in Vit. Isocrat. 
 
 *«^ Vit. Dec. Orat. in Vit. Lycurg. 
 
 ^"^ Diog. ii. 65, and there Menage, 
 cf. 72, 74. He is said to have taken 
 from 500 to 1000 drachmas, although 
 
 must be refen-ed to the time of Socra- I others refer these accounts to Iso- 
 
 tes alone. 
 
 ^«« Plat. Ilipp. § 5. For further in- 
 formation concerning Ilippias, see 
 
 crates. 
 
 *8* Plat. CratyL init. Aristot. Rhet. 
 iii. 14, Philost. ut sup. 12, Schol. Aris- 
 
 Suidas, Philostr. vit. Soplu i. 1, 11, ' toph. Nub. 360, Suidas in v. IIpoStKoi/, 
 
 Apulej. Florid, p. 346, ed. Elm. 
 
 ^»' Plat. Apol. Socrat. p. 20, B. 
 
 ^^- Demosth. cont. Lacrit. p. 938, 17, 
 Plutarch, in Vit. Demosth. and Vit. X. 
 
 Eudoc. Ion. p. 365. 
 
 *"* Van Spaan (Ruhnken) de Antiph. 
 p. 809, tom. vii. of Reiske's Orators. 
 V. didypufXfjM. 
 
 587 I„
 
 Cn. XXII.] INTEREST OF MONEY. 123 
 
 drachina^^^ ; a stater with women of middling condition^^% but 
 the price of a Lais was 10,000 drachmas for a night"". Other 
 prices may be seen in Lysias'^', and the author of the epistles 
 of uEschines"^ 
 
 Chapter XXII. 
 
 Interest of Money in Attica. Money Changers and Bankers. 
 Loans on Mortgage, 
 
 The rate of interest in Greece was expressed either by the 
 number of oboli or drachmas which were paid by the month 
 for each mina that was borrowed, or by the part of the princi- 
 pal that was paid as interest either annually, or for the whole 
 time of the loan. According to the first method of speaking, 
 interest of 10 per cent, per annum is called at 5 oboli (eVl 
 Trevre o^oXoh), of 12 per cent, at a drachma (eVl Bpaxf^fj), of 
 16 per cent, at 8 oboli {iir o/crco o^oXoh), of 18 per cent, at 9 
 oboli {kir evvea ojSoXoh), and of 24 or 36 per cent, at 2 or 3 
 drachmas (iirl Bvcrl, rpipl hpay^iials) : according to the other 
 method, the rates of the third, fifth, sixth, eighth, and tenth 
 parts of the principal, either annually or for any specified term, 
 are 33|^, 20, lef^ 121, and 10 per cent, {tokol eTTLTpiToc, 
 €7rL7r€fjLT0t, €(f)eKTOi, iiToyBooi, eTTiSeKaroty^^, 
 
 Passages in the ancient writers leave no room for doubt 
 that the expressions above cited have the sense which I have 
 assigned to them ; and that in the first method of expression, 
 the specified number of oboli and drachmas, was the amount of 
 interest to be paid by the month, and in the other the portion 
 of the principal was interest to be paid either annually, or in 
 
 ^8 Hesych. in v. TpiavronopvT], writings of the ancients, signify 1^, l^r 
 Athen. vi. p. 241, E, Aristoph. Tliesm. &c., as the beginner may learn from 
 1207. The diobolares are well known, my ^Memoir uher die Bildung der Welt^ 
 
 ^^^ Theopompus the comic poet ap. 
 Poll. ix. 59. 
 
 *9" Sotion ap. Gell. i. 8, 8. 
 
 *»i Cont. Simon, pp. 147, 148. 
 
 ?9i Pseud-zEschiu. Epist. 7- 
 
 ^^^ The words eniTptTOS, iniTeTapTos, 
 6i.c. in the mathematical and musical 
 
 seele im Tim'dos des Plat on, Studien,, 
 I8I7, part i. p. 50. That in the 
 reckoning of interest they mean ^, &c. 
 has been already remarked by Salma- 
 sius de M. U. I. Compare Schneider 
 ad Xeuoph. de Vectig. p. lo3.
 
 124 INTEREST OF MONEY. [bK. I. 
 
 cases of bottomry for the time of the ship's passage specified in 
 the agreement. Some earlier writers, however, whom Salma- 
 sius has already refuted with needless minuteness, have main- 
 tained the absurd notion, that the tenth, eighth, sixth, fifth, and 
 third parts of the loan were interest to be paid monthly, or in 
 agreements of bottomry even daily; nor can we feel otherwise 
 than astonished to find that Barthelemy"^, repeating the asser- 
 tion of Petit, considers 16 per cent, as monthly interest. The 
 main source of this error lies in the supposition, that all inte- 
 rest was paid by the month, which, without doubt, was fre- 
 quently the case"^: but not only is it impossible that in bot- 
 tomr)' bonds, the interest could have been paid monthly, as the 
 borrower was neither able nor obliged to pay it until after his 
 return ; but even in mortgages, the annual payment of interest 
 was not uncommon^®^: nor if in ancient Greece, *at all times, 
 and in all places, interest had been paid by the month, w^ould 
 it follow from the names of the interest of the third, fifth, sixth, 
 and eighth j^arts, that those portions of the principal were paid 
 monthly, any more than at present, when it is paid quarterly or 
 half yearly, it folloW' s from the expression that a sum of m oney 
 is lent at 5 per cent., that 5 per cent, is to be paid every quarter 
 or half year. We may also remark, omitting the agreements of 
 bottomry, which did not exactly run a year, that the interest of 
 the tenth part [tokol iiriheKaroi) is the same as the interest of 
 5 oboli, of the eighth part (12^ per cent.) nearly the same as 
 the interest of one drachma (12 per cent.), of the sixth part 
 (16f per cent.) nearly the same as the rate at 8 oboli (16 per 
 per cent.), of the 5th part (20 per cent.) nearly the same as the 
 rate at 9 oboli (18 per cent.), and of the third part (33 i) as the 
 rate of 3 drachmas (36 per cent.) : but the examples which will 
 be presently quoted, prove that they are not therefore to be 
 
 ^^* Anachars. torn. iv. p. 372. dent from the above-quoted inserip- 
 
 •^^^ Aristoph. Nub. init. and 751 | tion. In the Orchomenian Inscription 
 
 sqq. (Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 15«9,) the 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. Tolycl. p. 1225, 15. j rate of interest is also fixed by the 
 
 Inscript. ap. Montfaucon. Diar. Ital. ; month, but it did not necessarily follow 
 
 p. 412. Even when the rate of in- tliat the money should therefore be 
 
 terest was fixed by the month, it paid every month. 
 
 might be paid by the year,_as is evi-
 
 CH. XXII.] INTEREST OF MONEY. 125 
 
 taken as identical; and each expression must be understood 
 precisely in its strict meaning as it stands, since the lenders 
 would never have made use of indefinite expressions. It was 
 not until the age of Justinian that the Centesima, which is 
 exactly equal to the interest at a drachma, was identified with 
 the interest of the eighth part [tokos iiroyhoos) or 12i per 
 cent., as Salmasius correctly remarks ; although he himself, in 
 speaking of more ancient times, does not always accurately dis- 
 tinguish between the rates of interest which I have mentioned 
 as only slightly differing. 
 
 From this preliminary investigation into the method of 
 expressing the rate of interest, it follows that in Greece in- 
 terest was not so low as in modern states, and at Rome in the 
 age of Cicero : the lowest rate at Athens appears to have been 
 10 per cent., the highest 36 per cent.; the latter is not even 
 exceeded by any examples of interest received upon bottomry, 
 although these were, in fact, higher than they appear, since the 
 time of a ship's voyage for which the money was generally lent, 
 w^as shorter than a year. I can find no authority for the state- 
 ment of Casaubon*®^, that they sometimes obtained an interest 
 of 4 drachmas a month, although usurers took, without reserve, 
 as much as they could extort. Interest equal to half the prin- 
 cipal [rj/iLoXcos tokos), first occurs a considerable time after the 
 Christian era, in a case of a loan of products of the soil to be 
 repaid in kind^®\ 
 
 The cause of the high rate of interest can only be, that it 
 was then more difficult than now to procure a loan of money, 
 or, what is equivalent, that there was a greater demand for 
 money to be borrowed, and a smaller quantity to be lent. But 
 that, in general, this circumstance was not owing to the insuffi- 
 cient quantity of money in circulation, appears to be e^ddent 
 from this, that if the quantity of coin in circulation was small, 
 the demand for it would necessarily be small likewise, on 
 account of the low prices of commodities ; and also from the 
 fact, that landed . estates bore a rent equal to 8 per cent, of 
 their value, and even more than 12 per cent, for the lease of 
 
 Ad Theophrast. Char. 6. '^^ Salmas. de M. U. viii.
 
 126 
 
 INTEREST OF MONEY. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 the whole property^'^ ; so that the rate of interest does not 
 appear to depend upon the quantity of money in circulation, but 
 to have a common origin with rent. 
 
 The chief reasons, therefore, why money was not willingly 
 lent out at a low interest, appear to be, that any person who 
 wished to carry on business with it himself, might obtain a high 
 profit by employing it in commerce or manufactures^"", in the 
 same way that any one who managed his own property himself, 
 on account of the smaller expense of slave-labour, would neces- 
 sarily have made a greater net profit than at the present time 
 under a different combination of circumstances. Add to this 
 that credit was at a low ebb, which was occasioned by the 
 defective morality and the imperfection of the civil constitution 
 and laws of the different states, and especially by the difficulty 
 of obtaining redress for injuries in a foreign country. Even the 
 legislation of Solon, by which the rights of individuals were 
 more accurately defined, struck at the root of the security of 
 the creditor, by taking away his right over the body of the 
 debtor ; and it was shown by the measure called the Seisach- 
 theia, how little respect the state had for the security of pro- 
 perty, whether by this ordinance merely the value of the cur- 
 rency was depreciated, or the rate of interest also was diminished, 
 or whether, in certain cases at least, a complete extinction of 
 all debts was effected by it^°* ; nor was the severity of the laws 
 upon debt sufficient to produce any great security in the lend- 
 ing of money, as the administration of them was entrusted to 
 ill-regulated courts of justice, and the fraudulent debtor had at 
 his command every species of subterfuge and dishonest con- 
 trivance against the creditor. 
 
 The business of the bankers^"^ may lastly have contributed 
 to raise the rate of interest, as these usurers took money at a 
 moderate premium from persons who would not occupy them- 
 selves with the management of their own property^"^ in order 
 
 *^^ See below, chap. xxiv. 
 ^°° See above, chap. ix. 
 «»' SeePlut. Solon. 14. 
 •^"^ Concerning which see particu- 
 larly Salraasius de Fonore Trapezitico 
 
 and de Usuris, and the acute Heral- 
 dus, Animadv. in Salmas. Obs. ii. 24, 
 25. 
 
 ^"^ Thus e. g. Demosthenes' father 
 kept a part of his capital in the hands
 
 CIl. XXII.J MONEY CHANGERS AND BANKERS, 
 
 127 
 
 to lend it with profit to others, and thus to a certain degree 
 obtained possession of a monopoly. Trading with borrowed 
 money composed the chief part of the business of the bankers*'^'', 
 although they sometimes employed capital of their own in that 
 manner ; the exchange of money at an agio""'* was by no means 
 their exclusive employment. Although they were generally of 
 a low origin, freedmen, aliens, or persons who had been admit- 
 ted as citizens, they aimed less at connecting themselves with 
 good families, than at pecuniary gain®°^; but they became pos- 
 sessed of great credit, which existed for the principal houses 
 through the whole of Greece, and were thus efi'ectively sup- 
 ported in their business^"^; they even maintained such a repu- 
 tation, that not only were they considered as secure merely by 
 virtue of their calling, but such confidence was placed in them, 
 that business was transacted with them without witnesses^°% 
 and as is now done in courts of justice, money and contracts of 
 debt were deposited with them, and agreements were concluded 
 or cancelled in their presence^°^ The importance of their 
 business is shown by the great wealth of Pasion, whose bank 
 annually produced a net profit of 100 minas^^°; there are, how- 
 ever, instances of their failing and losing every thing^'^ It is 
 scarcely necessary to show that they took a high rate of interest; 
 their loans on the deposit of goods are, without other testimony, 
 sufficient to prove it^^^. The Athenian bankers obtained 36 
 per cent., a rate which hardly occurs among honest people, 
 except in the case of bottomry. 
 
 The common usurers {TOKoy\v<l>ocjtoculliones,rjfiepoBav€i,<TTal), 
 who made a profit of the necessities of the poor or the extrava- 
 gance of the young, demanded, according to the faithful descrip- 
 
 of bankers, Dem. cont. Aphob. i. p. 
 816. 
 
 «"^ Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 948, 
 sup. 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. Trapez. 21, Demosth. 
 de fals. Leg. p. 376, 2, cont. Polycl. p. 
 1216, 18, Pollux, iii. 84, \-ii. 170. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. pro Phonn. p. 953. 
 
 ^^^ Cf. Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 958, 
 sup. cont. Polycl. p. 1224, 3. 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. Trapezit. 2. 
 
 ^"5 Demosth. cont. Callip. p. 1243, 
 8, cont. Dionysod. p. 1287, 20. 
 
 ^'•^ Demosth. pro Phonn. p. 946, 25. 
 
 ^^^ Dem. pro Phorm. p. 959, cont. 
 Stephan. i. p. 1120, 20 sqq. Ulpian ad 
 Demosth. cont. Timocrat. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. cont. Nicostrat. p. 
 1249, 10.
 
 128 
 
 MONEY CHANGERS AND BANKERS. 
 
 [bk. I, 
 
 tion of Theophrastus^'% as much as an obolus and a half a day, 
 for each drachma; and the practice which was prevalent in the 
 times of Plutarch, of immediately subtracting the interest from 
 the sum borrowed, and again lending it out upon interest*"*, 
 had probably arisen in the flourishing times of Athens. On 
 account of this high rate of interest, and the severity with 
 which they enforced the payment of it, frequently seizing the 
 houses and property of their debtors, and as lenity was foreign 
 to their character, or indeed any other consideration but that of 
 their own gain, the bankers and money-lenders drew upon 
 themselves the merited hatred of all, as being the most infamous 
 of human beings^ ''^. 
 
 Money was lent without interest from motives of friendship 
 or kindness, even without a written bond and any security or 
 pledge, either with or without witnesses (')(^€Lp6Borov, aavy- 
 ypacf^ovY^^; sometimes wdth an acknowledgment (x^cpoypaipov), 
 which was usually written upon papyrus ; or with a formal and 
 solemn instrument [crvyypacjir]), which was written by a third 
 person in a diptychon of waxen tablets, signed by witnesses, 
 and given in charge to a banker® '^ The security was either 
 made over to the creditor or not ; in the latter case it was 
 security in a more limited sense, in the former it was the pledge 
 {ivixvpovY^^: the security in the more confined signification 
 was generally of land, but sometimes of moveables, for instance, 
 slaves, and especially in cases of bottomry, the goods, the ship, 
 and the outstanding freightage-money; although the pledges 
 were generally of moveable property, we sometimes find that 
 land and houses were given in pledge, and indeed, on account 
 of their safety, were common for dowries and leases of orphans' 
 property. 
 
 To lend upon a person's own body (Savetfetv eVl crco^ari) 
 
 *'^ Char. 6, and there Casaubon; cf. 
 Herald. Anim. in Salmas. Obs. ad I. 
 A. et Rii. 21. 
 
 ^'* Plutarch, de vitando acre alieno, 
 4. 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. cent. Stephan. i. p. 
 1122, extr. and ]). 1123, sup. cont. 
 Panta3n. pp. 98 1 , 982. Antiphanes the 
 
 comic poet in the Mia-onovrjpos ap. 
 Athen. vi. p. 22G, E, cf. Herald, ut 
 sup. ii. 24, 1, 2. 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. cont. Tinioth. p. 
 12, Salmas. de M. U. x. p. :J81. 
 
 ^'7 Salmas. ibid. 
 
 *"^ Salmas. ut sup. 11, 
 
 185,
 
 CII. XXII.] 
 
 LOANS OX MORTGAGE. 
 
 129 
 
 was prohibited in Athens from the time of Solon"' % in imita- 
 tion, as Diodorus supposes, of the Egyptian law; in other 
 states this cruel and barbarous custom remained in force, 
 although it was not allowed to take even agricultural implements 
 in pawn®^". Arms could neither be taken nor given in pawn 
 at Athens"^*. There were also public books of debt in Greece, 
 like the German registers of mortgages ; but they are not men- 
 tioned as having existed at Athens. Mortgaged lands, how- 
 ever, were distinguished by stone tablets or pillars, upon which 
 the debt and the creditor's name were inscribed (o/3ot)^": a 
 custom of extreme antiquity, which existed before the time of 
 Solon, who himself declares, that by his constitution the stones 
 which had been before standing upon all estates were removed, 
 as he by some method or other had released or relieved the 
 debtors. 
 
 If the principal, together with the security, was not exposed 
 to destruction, and the creditor, according to his contract, liable 
 to no loss, the interest was certain, and was called land-interest 
 or mortgage {tokol eyyvoi, or eyyeooLy^^, Neither the interest 
 of money lent upon mortgage, of which I shall next speak, nor 
 upon bottomry, was fixed by law; and even, if we suppose it to 
 be true, as was affirmed by Androtion, that Solon lowered the 
 
 *^' Diog. Laert. and Plutarch in the 
 Life of Solon, also the latter in his 
 Essay de vitando sere aheno, 4. 
 
 ^^ Salmas. ut sup. xvii. p. 749. 
 
 '^■^^ Petit. Leg. Att. viii. 1, C. 
 
 ^^^ Demosthenes in many passages, 
 which have been collected by Reiske 
 in the Index, p, 544, Pollux iii. 85, ix. 0, 
 Etyniol. and Harpocrat. in vv. aariKTov 
 and opoff, Hesych. in vv. opo^ and copicr- 
 fifVT], Lex. Seg. p. 285, Photius in opos 
 in several articles. Cf. Salmas. ut sup. 
 XV. They were o-rJyXai, stone tablets 
 or pillars ; the Romans (see Vales, 
 upon Maussac's notes to Harpocration) 
 likewise used tahulce of the same na- 
 ture : at Athens, however, they appear 
 not to have been of wood, although 
 tlie Etymologist and Lex. Seg. p. 192, 
 
 5, p. 285, 12, call them aaviSes accord- 
 ing to a later custom, perhaps from a 
 misapprehension of a passage in the 
 first speech against Aristogeiton, p. 
 791, 11. It should be observed, how- 
 ever, that it was by no means neces- 
 sary to set up these stones, see Herald. 
 Anim. in Salmas. Obser. ad I. A. and 
 R. iv. 3, 8. (See a paper by the Au- 
 thor on this subject, reprinted in the 
 Museum Criticum, No. viii. p. 622, 
 sqq.) 
 
 ^'^'^ See Salmas. ut sup. iii. The 
 manuscripts sometimes give the former 
 word, whicli Salmasius declares to be 
 the correct forai, and sometimes the 
 latter : both appear to have been in 
 use, but where either is more correctly 
 used, is not easy to detennine.
 
 130 LOANS ON MORTGAGE. [bK. I. 
 
 interest of all debts which existed before his time, yet he per- 
 mitted every person afterwards to lend his money at whatever 
 rate he could obtain"*; and only in the single instance of a 
 man^s separating from his lawful wife, and not immediately 
 returning her dowry, the rate of 9 oboli (18 per cent.) was fixed 
 by law, probably because this was the ordinary rate at the time 
 when this regulation was made^". Even in the age of Lysias 
 and Isseus, this high interest was not usurious ; the latter 
 orator^^^ relates it as an ordinar}^ occurrence, that a person had 
 lent 40 minas at 9 oboli, and had received from them a return 
 of 720 drachmas a year; and Timarchus borrowed upon the 
 very same terms^^^. 
 
 The interest of 8 oboli (16 per cent.) occurs in Demosthe- 
 nes^^^; the interest of a drachma (12 per cent.), which is at the 
 present day the common rate in the Levant^ was frequent in 
 the age of Demosthenes, but it was, as appears from the orator^s 
 own words, considered low, although a talent lent out at this 
 rate would have produced an annual return of 720 drachmas, 
 upon which a small family could live^^^ The interest of 5 
 oboli, or of the tenth part, was chiefly in use among friends"", 
 and is opposed to the interest of the third part: in a story, 
 related in Aristotle^s rhetoric, of Mcerocles, who lived in the 
 age of Demosthenes, it is considered as moderate^^'. 
 
 From 12 to 18 per cent, appear then to have been the com- 
 
 ^^ To dpyvpLov (TTcia-ifiov elvai i(\> | Niehuhr Hist. Rom. vol. ii. p. 61, &c. 
 oTToo-o) av ^ovkqraL 6 bavei^cov. Lex i In an inscription in Miiratori vol. ii. 
 ap. Lys. cont. Theomnest. p. 360. ; p. DLXxviii. i. eVaroo-rtatoy tokos is 
 Si-^crai then had the meaning of j mentioned, evidently translated from 
 Sai/eio-ai, from the money being weigh- tisurce centesimce, and thus furnishes a 
 ed when it was lent ; thence also the means of determining the age of the 
 
 word o^oXoaTaTTjs. Orus ap. Etymol. 
 in V. o^eXia-Kos. 
 
 6" Orat. c. Neser. p. 1362, 9, De- 
 mosth. c. Aphob. i. p. 818, 27, of. Sal- 
 mas, de M. U. iv. p. 159. 
 
 626 De Hagn. Hered. p. 293. 
 
 6^7 ^sch. c. Timarch. p. 127. 
 
 "8 Cont. Nicostrat. p. 1250, 18. 
 
 62» Demosth. c. Aphob. i. p: 816, 11, 
 p. 820, 20, p. 824, 22, ii. p. 839, 24, 
 iEschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 497, comp. 
 
 inscription. 
 
 630 Demosth. c. Onetor. i. p. 866, 4. 
 
 631 Aristot. Rhet. iii. 10, with the 
 slight alteration of Salmasius de M. U. 
 ii. p. 41, also in the spurious (Econo- 
 mics of Aristotle 2, 3, ed. Schneid. 
 67rtSe/caroi tokoi occur on the occasion 
 of a sequestration imposed by the 
 Byzantines upon all vessels, which, 
 however, must not be considered as a 
 common occurrence.
 
 CH. XXII.] 
 
 LOANS ON MORTGAGE. 
 
 131 
 
 monest rates of interest at Athens ; the only manner in which 
 I can explain why Salmasius^^^ considered the interest of the 
 sixth part, or 16f per cent, as the most usual at Athens, is, 
 that he confounds this rate of interest with others of similar 
 amount. Several examples of higher rates of interest occur. 
 Demus, the son of the celebrated Pyrilampes, who had been 
 sent as ambassador to Persia, offered to pawn a golden cup to 
 Aristophanes for 16 minas, which he had received from the 
 king of Persia, and to redeem it in a short time for 20^^^ 
 ^schines, the Socratic philosopher, wishing to set up a manu- 
 factory of ointments, borrowed money of a banker at 3 drach- 
 mas {S6 per cent.) whereby he lost, until he procured the same 
 sum from another person at 9 oboli^^*. 
 
 The rate of interest in other Grecian states was regulated in 
 a similar manner. The Clazomenians paid the commanders 
 of their mercenary troops 4 talents a year, as the interest of a 
 debt of 20 talents at the rate of the fifth part {t6ko9 eirl- 
 irefiirTosY^^, The rate of mortgage in the Bosporus was some- 
 times the sixth part (to/co9 e(f)eKTos), at which Phormion, as 
 mentioned in Demosthenes®^^ pretended to have paid 560 
 drachmas for 120 Cyzicenic staters, each reckoned at 28 Attic 
 drachmas, at 16f per cent. In Orchomenus in Bceotia, interest 
 occurs of several drachmas for a month ; and in a Corcyrsean 
 decree it is ordered that certain monies shall not be lent out 
 either at a higher or lower rate than at 2 drachmas a month 
 (24 per cent.)"^, where bottomry cannot possibly be meant. 
 The epobelia of Plato in his Treatise upon Laws*'" (according 
 to which the taking of usury was to have been entirely for- 
 bidden in the second ideal state) is not a rate of interest, as 
 
 «32 ut sup. i. p. 10. 
 
 ^^ Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 629, 
 sqq. 
 
 *** Lys. Fragm. p. 4. 
 
 ^^^ See the (Economics attributed 
 to Aristotle. 
 
 "6 Cont. Phorm. p. 914, 10. Con- 
 cerning the €<peKTOi TOKOS comp. also 
 Harpocration, Suidas, Photius, and 
 Zonaras in v. e^e/croff tokos. The ac- 
 
 count given by Photius in v. 6<^f<crous 
 TOKovs, and by Lex. Seg. p. 257, is 
 entirely devoid of sense, and is founded 
 upon a false derivation, and a false 
 accentuation, viz, €(J)€kt6s. 
 
 *^7 See the inscriptions quoted in 
 note 596. 
 
 «38 xi. p. 921, C, cf. V. p. 742, C ; 
 Salmas. de M. U. i. p. 12 ; Schneider 
 ad Xenoph. de Vectig. p. 182. 
 K 2
 
 132 
 
 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. 
 
 [bk. I. 
 
 some have supposed, but a fine, such as the Athenian epobelia, 
 to be fixed like interest by the month; that is to say, if a 
 person neglected to pay the wages of any servant for the space 
 of a year, he was, as a punishment for his dilatory conduct, to 
 pay the epobelia, or an obolus to every drachma, for each 
 month of the time. 
 
 Chapter XXIII. 
 Loans upon Bottomry. 
 
 A still higher profit was obtained by capitahsts, allowance 
 being made for accidents, by maritime interest {tokos vaurtKos, 
 €AcSo(7ty)"' or bottomry, in which, according to the Grecian 
 custom, tlie ship, the cargo, or the money received for pas- 
 sengers and freightage, were answerable for the principal. The 
 loan appears to have been most frequently made upon the 
 goods (eVl roi<; (popTLOcS) eirl rols y^prj^acnVi eirl rfj ifiTropla), 
 more rarely upon the vessel (eVl rfj vrjl, eirl tg) 7fKoi(o), and the 
 money received for passengers and for freightage {iirl tm 
 vauXo))****; in a case mentioned by Demosthenes^**, in which a 
 trierarch borrowed money upon a ship that belonged to the 
 state, and to the command of which he expected a successor, 
 it is probable that the only security given was the ship's 
 furniture, which was the private property of the trierarch. 
 
 This species of interest, which was so odious at Rome, does 
 not appear to have given offence in Greece, and especially at 
 Athens, as being a commercial town ; it was, however, exposed 
 
 •^' See Salmas. v. p. 19; Schneider 
 ut sup. p. 181. 
 
 "^ Concerning the expressions in 
 use see Schneider ut sup. p. 180. An 
 instance of money being borrowed 
 upon the passage money and the ves- 
 Bcl occurs in Demosth. in Lacrit. p. 
 933, 22, and upon the passage money, 
 as it appears, Diphilus in the passage 
 quoted below ; and of money lent upon 
 the vessel, Demosth. ibid, and in Dio- 
 
 nysod. p, 1283, 18; comp. the argu- 
 ment p. 1282, 4. What proofs Hudt- 
 walcker (von den Diateten, p. 140) 
 can bring in favour of his assertion, 
 that at Athens, in cases of Fenus 
 nauticum, the ship was always hypo- 
 thecated, I am unable to guess. The 
 contraiy is indeed e\adent from the 
 passages quoted by Schneider and 
 myself. 
 
 "*^ Cent. Polycl. p. 1212 sup.
 
 CH. XXIII.] 
 
 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY, 
 
 133 
 
 to much risk, as the loss of the security also brought with it 
 the loss of both principal and interest : agreements of bottomry, 
 in which the lender was not liable to the risk, were prohibited 
 by the laws of Rhodes, that is, nobody could take such high 
 interest as was customary in bottomry, without exposing him- 
 self to the danger of the loss : but since by the Athenian law, 
 every person could take as high interest as he could obtain, 
 this restriction did not exist at Athens ; and such contracts as 
 the Rhodian law prohibited, have no connexion with agreements 
 of bottomry, as there would in those cases be either no security 
 or one which was not at sea®**. 
 
 Agreements of bottomry were rendered binding by means 
 of an instrument styled a maritime contract {vavTiKr) avy- 
 ypa<l)r}y*^, which was deposited in the hands of a banker"*. 
 A document of this kind is preserved entire in the speech of 
 Demosthenes against the Paragraphe of Lacritus, and part of 
 another in the speech against Dionysodorus. The money was 
 lent for a fixed time, and for the voyage to a particular place or 
 country, and the debtor was bound to go to the place pointed 
 out in the agreement, subject to a heavy penalty for the breach 
 of this condition'*\ If it was only lent for the voyage out- 
 wards {erepoTrXovs), the principal and interest were to be paid 
 at the place of destination, either to the creditor himself if he 
 went the voyage, or to some other person commissioned to 
 receive it; of this latter description was the Cermacoluthus, 
 who was frequently sent with the ship**' ; if the contract was 
 for the voyage both inwards and outwards {a^<t>oTep6ir\ovs:)y 
 the payment was made after the return. 
 
 In these agreements there was generally a double security, 
 the debtor being bound in goods to twice the amount of the 
 loan, without being able to raise other money upon them"' ; 
 and in agreements for voyages both inwards and outwards, if 
 
 ^*^ Concerning the meaning of the 
 Hhodian law, which Sahnasius had not 
 perceived, see Hudtwalcker de Fenore 
 Nautico Romano, p. 7. 
 
 "3 Demosth. c. Lacrit. p. 932, 3 ; 
 of. Lex. Seg. p. 283, and others. 
 
 "* Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 908, 20. 
 
 ^** Demosth. c. Dionysod. p. 1286 
 sup. 
 
 6« Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 909,24; 
 p. 914,28. 
 
 ^*^ Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 908 sqq. 
 c. Lacrit. pp. 925—928.
 
 134 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. [bK. I. 
 
 the goods given as a security were sold, fresh commodities of 
 equal value were to be reladen^^^ The severity of the laws 
 against those who withdrew the security from a creditor, lias 
 been already remarked ; but it was usual for a penalty to be 
 also fixed in the agreements, if the debtor should not repay 
 the entire loan, or should act otherwise contrary to the con- 
 ditions ; for example, of twice the amount of the principal, or 
 of 5000 drachmas on a loan of 2000'". Until the time of 
 repayment the security, if it was saved, was to be left untouched 
 for the creditor : and sometimes, for greater security, even the 
 whole property of the debtor was made answerable by a particular 
 stipulation"''. The money of orphans could not, according to 
 law, be lent on bottomry, although this regulation was often 
 violated*'^ 
 
 As the hazard varied materially according to the length of 
 the time, the distance of the voyage, the danger to which the 
 vessels was exposed from storms, rocks, hostile fleets, pirates, 
 or licensed privateers, it is less easy to conceive that there 
 should have been an usual rate of interest in Greece for money 
 lent on bottomry, than for the mortgage of land; and the 
 assertion of Salmasius"^, that the rate of interest of the fifth 
 part (20 per cent.) was the most common at Athens, is entirely 
 devoid of foundation. The interest upon money lent only for 
 the voyage outwards, must moreover have been less than that 
 for the two voyages inwards and outwards, particularly since 
 passengers who accompanied the master of a vessel, carrying 
 at the same time sums of money with them, would naturally be 
 the more ready to lend it to the captain, as they must have 
 still incurred the same risk that arose from bottomry, if they 
 took it with them without interest. The 10 or 12 per cent, 
 interest upon money lent on bottomry mentioned by Di- 
 philus"^ must undoubtedly be understood only of the passage 
 
 "^ Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 909, 20. 
 
 ®^^ Demosth. c. Diouysod. p. 1294, 
 12 ; c. riiorm. p. 915, 1 ; p. 916, 2?. 
 
 "" Deed in the Oration against La- 
 critus. I 
 
 65) 
 
 "^ De M. U. I. p. 10 ; v. p. 209, 
 where his reference to Xenophon 
 proves nothing. 
 
 ^*^ In the passage which Salmasius 
 |uotes p. 35. 
 
 Lys. Fragni. p. 37. Also the ' Els 5eV eVi rfj fipa yfvoueuat kuI dwdfKi 
 case in Lys. c. Diogit. p. 908. ' Aa/3au/ to. vavXaKai Saj/et' epvyytwcau.
 
 CH. XXIII.] 
 
 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. 
 
 135 
 
 outwards; as also the interest of the eighth part (12i per cent.) 
 in Demosthenes"*, which the trierarch ApoUodorus lent to the 
 
 "* Demosth. cont. Polycl. p. 1211, 
 extr. 'ElcrayyeXOivTOiv de otl Bv^dv- 
 
 Tioc dvayKa^ovcri top (tItov 
 
 i^aipeicrOai, daveicrdfievos eyo) dpyvpiov 
 TTapd Xaipedrjfiov flip rod ' Ava(p\v(TTiov 
 TrevTeKaideKa fivds enl tokov, eTrraKOffLas 
 de dpaxp-as Trapci "NiKiTrTrov tov vovk- 
 Xrjpov vavTiKov dveiXofxrju, 6s eTV)(ev &>v 
 iv '2T)(TT<Of inoyboov, Kal nefxyj/as Evk- 
 TTjfiova . . . eKeXevad fiot avrov vavras 
 
 fxio-dMO-ao-Bai This is the old 
 
 reading, except that I have restored 
 fjivds for dpaxP'ds from the manuscripts 
 with Salmasius de M. U. V. p. 219, 
 and Reiske ; whether 'Apx^^p-ovy the 
 reading of some manuscripts, and 
 oKTaKoa-ias, which is approved of by 
 Salmasius, should also be replaced, I 
 leave undecided. 'Aj/eiXo'fiT^i/ is put by 
 Anacoluthon for dveXofievos, which is 
 seldom used with /ueV and Se : an in- 
 stance however occurs in Herod, vi. 
 13, Speovres dfxa fxev iovaav dra^irjv 
 
 TToXXrjV €K TOiV '1(01/0)1/ ibcKOVTO TOVS 
 
 Xoyovs, dfxa de KarefjiaiveTO (T(^l eivai 
 ddvvara ret ^acnXeos TrprjyfiaTa vnep- 
 /SaXeV^ai, ev t€ eTricrrdfievot . . . which 
 is precisely similar to the passage of 
 Demosthenes ; and as KaT€(paiveTo 
 might have been omitted in the former, 
 so might dveiXojjLrjv in the latter sen- 
 tence ; vi. 19, expW^V ^ttikoivov xPW~ 
 rrjpcov, TO fxeu is avrovs tovs ^Apyeiovs 
 (f)€pov, TTjV de 7Tapev6r]Krfv exprjcre es 
 MiXrjaLovs. Also vi. 25, ad fin. Simi- 
 larly also in Herod, viii. 69, Trpos p-ev 
 Ev/Soi't; (T^eas edeXoKaKeeiv, as ov 
 napeovTOS avrov, rore de avros rrapea- 
 KevacTTO derjaaaOai vavpax^ovras, the 
 transition from the indirect infinitive 
 to the indicative. There are also 
 other difficulties in this passage, which 
 Salmasius and Reiske have been quite 
 unable to clear up. The notes of the 
 latter commentator are mere trifling, 
 as he had no distinct notion of the 
 Greek system of interest. 'Etti tokov, 
 
 for which Hier. Wolf wishes to sub- 
 stitute the more convenient expression 
 of eVt ro'/co), was thought too indefi- 
 nite. Salmasius corrects eyyvco, and 
 Reiske eyyeiov tokov, or eyyeiav tokohv ; 
 if however these words refer at all to 
 the rate of interest, one should rather 
 expect some more particular percentage 
 than the generic term. * Os ervx^v Siv iv 
 2r](TTa cannot be referred to vuvtikov, 
 the latter word being in the neuter 
 gender, as in the parallel passage of 
 Xenophon quoted below, Demosth. 
 cont. Aphob. i. p. 816, 26, vavTiKo. 
 ejBdoprjKopra pvds, and elsewhere. But 
 Salmasius' improbable conjectures o 
 and bvf are the less admissible, because 
 it cannot be supposed that there was 
 some one rate of interest in general 
 use at Sestos, without any distinction 
 of the risk, Reiske, without the 
 slightest authority, has placed the 
 words OS eTvx^v av iv "ErjaTa inoydoov 
 after eVi tokov : but the safest way is 
 to suppose that inoydoov means the 
 interest of money lent out on bottomry, 
 as it is explained in Lex. Seg. p. 252, 
 referring however falsely to a pledge 
 of goods : for it may be seen, by com- 
 paring Harpocration in v. inoydoov, 
 that the gloss refers to this passage. 
 
 My opinion is shortly this : inl tokov 
 is added, in order to remove any 
 doubt that Chaeredemus did not lend 
 the money to ApoUodorus, as being 
 his friend and countryman, without 
 interest, but, as is stated, eVi tokov, for 
 interest. The amount of this it was 
 not necessary to state, and it was per- 
 haps omitted as it might have been 
 unpleasant to Chaeredemus to have it 
 mentioned. The words 6s ervx^v S)v 
 iv ^rjCTTa can only be referred to Ni- 
 cippus by a very forced construction. 
 Most probably they belong to Xaipe- 
 drjpov p^v TOV ^Ava<pXv(TTiov ; for since 
 it might appear strange that the Ana-
 
 136 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. [bK. I. 
 
 ship-captain Nicippus, for the passage from Sestos to Athens, 
 but upon the condition that the trireme should first go to 
 Hierum to convoy vessels laden with corn, and that the prin- 
 cipal and interest should be paid at Athens, in case the ship 
 returned safely to port. The amount of this interest of the 
 eighth part, Harpocration correctly estimates at 3 oboli to the 
 tetradrachm. 
 
 Higher interest in loans upon bottomry frequently occurs ; 
 Xenophon in his Treatise upon the Revenues"* proposes to 
 erect public buildings for the convenience of merchants, as a 
 means of procuring a profitable return to the citizens, and he 
 supposes that the necessary sum could be collected by contri- 
 butions of different magnitude, but that each subscriber would 
 obtain an equal return of 3 oboli daily : he then proceeds to 
 remark, that those who put in 10 minas, would receive nearly 
 the interest of the fifth part, the rate which was commonly 
 given in bottomry [vavriKov o-p^^eSov iTTLTrefiTTTov), and those 
 who put in 5 minas, more than the interest of the third part ; 
 that the greater number, who subscribed a less sum, would 
 obtain an annual income of more than the capital which they 
 contributed, for example, for 1 mina nearly 2. The interest of 
 the fifth and third parts are e^'idently here considered as 
 common in cases of bottomry; the danger connected with this 
 method of investing money, is alluded to by Xenophon, when 
 he states it as an advantage to be expected from his proposals, 
 that " the profits would arise in the state itself, which appears 
 to him to be the most secure and lasting source of revenue.'^ 
 It is also manifest that the interest of the fifth part is here 
 precisely 20 per cent, and of the third part 33^ per cent, which 
 latter Harpocration"^ correctly fixes at 8 oboli for the tetra- 
 
 phlystian should be mentioned as being 
 at Sestos, it was natural to add that 
 he had been there accidentally. 
 
 «" 3, 7—1 4. The Avhole of tliis short 
 sketch of Xenoplion's, and of tlie er- 
 rors committed in tlie explanation of 
 it, is illustrated in book iv. ch. 21. 
 
 the false emendation proposed in p. 
 25 as superfluous. 
 
 '^'"^ In V. eTTirpiTats, referring to a 
 passage in Isaeus against Calhphon, 
 where witliout doubt the orator was 
 speaking of an agreement of bottomry. 
 Proceeding upon the example given 
 
 Here I only remark, that Salmasius de I by Harpocration of the method of 
 M. U, I. himself considei-s in p. 192, | reckoning, viz. eight oboli for the
 
 CII. XXIII.] 
 
 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. 
 
 137 
 
 drachm, and that the former ought not to be confounded with 
 the interest of 9 oboH, nor the latter with that at 3 drachmas (18 
 and 36 per cent.) For the year being reckoned with Xeno- 
 phon at 360 days, 3 oboli a day give an annual income of 180 
 drachmas, which for 10 minas are 18, and for 5 minas 36 per 
 cent: the former the author calls nearly the interest of the 
 fifth part, the latter more than that of the third part. 
 
 Other statements of the rate of interest likewise occur in 
 Demosthenes. Phormion had lent 20 minas for a voyage 
 inwards and outwards to the Pontus, at an interest of 6 minas, 
 that is, at 30 per cent*'". In the carelessly drawn instrument 
 in the speech against Lacritus, 3000 drachmas are lent upon 
 Mendsean wine, for a voyage from Athens to Mende or Scione, 
 and from thence to the Bosporus, the borrow^er being at liberty, 
 if he prefers it, to sail on to the left along the coast of the 
 Black Sea as far as the Borysthenes, at the rate of 225 for 1000 
 drachmas for the whole time of absence. In this however it is 
 supposed that the borrowers, Phaselitans by birth, are to com- 
 mence their voyage back from the Pontus before the early 
 rising of Arcturus, in the month Boedromion, about the 20th 
 of September, as the autumn [(f)6iv67r(opov) and with it the 
 dangers of navigation then commenced : instead of the interest 
 of 224 per cent., the higher rate of 30 per cent, or 300 for 1000 
 was how^ever to be paid, if the voyage back from the Pontus to 
 Hierum, upon the mouth of the Bosporus, should be under- 
 taken, as it sometimes was, after the rising of Arcturus"^. 
 
 Since the agreement extends to different places, and liberty 
 
 tetradrachm, the ignorant compiler of 
 the Lexicon Seguer. p. 253, confounds 
 the interest of the third part with the 
 rate of eight oboli. 
 
 "7 Demosth. cont. Phorm. p. 914,6. 
 
 ^^^ See Demosth. cont. Polycl. p. 
 1212, 14—24. The situation of Hierum 
 is in Bithynia, close to the Thracian 
 Bosporus; see Harpocration and Sui- 
 das in v. e<^' 'itpoz/, and passages re- 
 ferred to by Wolf ad Leptin. p. 259. 
 It was a port where the masters of 
 vessels returning from the Pontus put 
 
 in. The observations of Petit upon 
 this agreement are beneath all criti- 
 cism. Salmasius de M. U. V. p. 209, 
 sqq. explains it at full length, but he 
 has entu-ely lost sight of truth in the 
 interpretation of the third clause, and 
 by this means vitiates his whole ac- 
 count. Heraldus Anim. in Salmas. 
 Obs. ad I. A. et R. ii. 20, takes up 
 some of these errors, adding at the 
 same time some of his own. The 
 words iav fie fir] elo-ISaKmai, after which 
 a comma should be placed, cannot, as
 
 138 LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. [bK. I. 
 
 is allowed to the borrower to sail into the Pontus or not as he 
 prefers, there is at the end a farther limitation added, in the 
 event of the vessel not running into the Pontus. For in that case, 
 in order to avoid the tempests of the dog-days, the vessel was 
 to remain in the Hellespont, at the end of July, ten days from 
 the early rising of the dog-star (eVt kvvI), with which the latter 
 part of the summer {oTrcopa) begins, for the purpose of unlading 
 their cargo in a secure place, and then to return to Athens, 
 where they have to pay the interest fixed in the preceding year. 
 The addition of the words " in the preceding year'' is superflu- 
 ous, but correct : the instrument was signed in the spring, at 
 the time when navigation commenced; now the year ended and 
 began about the middle of summer, about the time of the sum- 
 mer solstice, and consequently the early rising of the dog-star 
 fell in the following year. In this last-mentioned stipulation 
 the lower rate of interest is meant; for the higher rate was only 
 to be paid if the return from the Pontus took place after the 
 rising of Arcturus, and thus if the ship did not run into the 
 Pontus, it did not apply at all. On the other hand, a new risk 
 might in this case arise, which would not exist if the vessel 
 entered the Pontus; the borrowers might return from the Hel- 
 lespont during the storms of the dog-days, which in case of a 
 voyage in the Pontus could not have taken place on account of 
 the greater distance; it is therefore fixed, that in the former 
 case, the vessel should remain in the Hellespont. 
 
 With regard to the security of the place where the goods 
 were to be disembarked, it is stipulated that no part of the 
 cargo should be discharged at any port where the Athenians 
 had the right of reprisal {pirov av fir] avXai coauv ^Adrjvaloi^) : 
 one should rather have expected this condition to have been 
 made with respect to places where this right had been granted 
 against Athenians (Kar'. ^K6r]vaicDv) : for the creditors, of whom 
 one is an Athenian, could not be afraid of the Athenians; 
 neither could the borrowers, since they traded at Athens, have 
 
 Salmasius imagines, be referred to the 
 passage out of the Hellespont into the 
 -■Egeau Sea, but ouly, as is evident 
 
 from the ^vhole agreement, to the 
 voyage into the Pontus.
 
 CH. XXIII.] LOANS UPON BOTTOMRY. 139 
 
 had anything to apprehend from the Athenians. This difficult}', 
 however^ is easily removed: for (not to mention that the trier- 
 archs at this precise period made reprisals upon the property 
 of persons whom the state had given them no authority to 
 plunder^ and consequently, that both Athenian and Phaselitan 
 property might easily have been captured by them), it is evident 
 that the moment any property passed either from or to any 
 place, against which the Athenians had given permission to 
 make reprisals, it became necessary to prohibit by a clause in 
 the agreement, the unlading of the goods at any such place, as 
 Athenian property, and consequently the security on which the 
 money was lent, would be seized there in retaliation, by those 
 whom the Athenians had plundered. 
 
 It is to be remarked that these commercial agreements were 
 in general made only for the time of a ship's voyage from the 
 spring till the autumn, and sometimes for a still shorter time, 
 in the case of a voyage which might be soon ended: a term was 
 commonly appointed for payment after the return of the vessel, 
 as for example, in the agreement in the speech against Lacritus, 
 the principal and interest were to be paid within twenty days 
 after the vessel returned to Athens, with the exception of what 
 might have been thrown overboard by the common consent of 
 all in the ship, or be taken away by the enemy. But the 
 interest in bottomry loans was often for a longer period. Thus, 
 according to the statement of Demosthenes, an individual bor- 
 rowed a sum of money in the month Metageitnion, in the mid- 
 dle of summer, and was only bound to repay it in the same 
 year, that is, before the beginning of the next summer'^'. In 
 this case a proportionally higher rate of interest was doubtless 
 given: as it was higher on account of the greater length of the 
 voyage'"". In most cases, however, the creditor withdrew his 
 capital in the winter for his own use. 
 
 «^» Demosth. cont. Dionysod. p. 1283, 19, p. 1284, 10. 
 ««« Ibid. p. 1286. extr.
 
 140 RENT OF LAND [bK. I. 
 
 Chapter XXIV. 
 
 Rent of Land and Houses in Attica, 
 
 From the rate of interest, we proceed to consider the rent of 
 houses and of other kinds of landed property. All the foreign- 
 ers and resident aliens, (the latter of whom were estimated with 
 their families at 45,000 persons), together with a proportionate 
 number of slaves, lived at Athens in hired lodgings. For it 
 is evident that foreigners could not become proprietors of 
 houses: if then they were at Athens for the sake of trade, or 
 for the purpose of conducting their law-suits, which often 
 detained them for years^®', they dwelled in hired lodgings, 
 excepting those individuals who were entertained as guests by 
 their friends. But the resident-aliens lived almost without 
 exception in the city or in the- sea-port towns, as they com- 
 posed the larger portion of the industrious classes; that they 
 could not own houses is in part evident from the statement of 
 Xenophon^^% and j^artly from the fact that no resident-alien 
 could safely lend money upon houses or other landed property, 
 a privilege which was confined to the citizens^". 
 
 Since then the resident-alien had not the right of owning 
 land, landed property was not a vahd security for him, as he 
 could never come into possession of it. Thus at Byzantium 
 the resident-aUens could not obtain the landed estates which 
 were mortgaged to them, because they had not the right of 
 owning landed property, until the state gave them permission 
 to hold their mortgaged lands, though not without their con- 
 senting to make a considerable deduction from the principaP". 
 The same practice prevailed in all Grecian States ; if then a 
 foreigner was created either a citizen or proxenus, the right of 
 holding landed property was expressly granted in the instru- 
 ment*^*; the Isoteles, however, were entitled to the possession 
 
 ««' Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. i. cf. 3, I ««^ See Pseud-Aristot. (Econ. ii.2,3. 
 
 "*^*" *^^* See the Arcadico-Cretan Decree 
 
 ««2 De Vectig. 2, 6. | in Chishull's Ant. Asiat. p. 119, the 
 
 «"» Demosth. pro^Phonn. p. 946. Bj2;autine Decree in Demosthenes de
 
 CH. XXIV.] AND HOUSES IN ATTICA. 141 
 
 of houses, which we learn from the fact that Lysias and Pole- 
 marchus had three houses in Athens^^^; with which their right 
 of working mines coincides. The letting of houses at Athens 
 was therefore an important branch of business; some built 
 lodging-houses {crvvoLKLat), and speculators {vavKXrjpoi, araO- 
 fiovxoi) rented whole houses in order to let them again to 
 under-tenants®". 
 
 House-rent, like interest, was paid or calculated by the 
 month, and the payment was generally claimed by means of a 
 slave'®^ The assertion of the grammarians^®^ that it was paid 
 by Pr)^taneias, is in this general sense absurd, though if only 
 understood of the houses which belonged to the state, is 
 unquestionably correct. Xenophon remarks that house-build- 
 ing, if undertaken prudently, was profitable, and might enrich 
 the speculator®^"; but the amount of house-rent in proportion 
 to the cost of building and to the value of the house must have 
 been very different, according to the situation, and have varied 
 with the increase or diminution in the population; after the 
 anarchy, the disturbances which then took place having much 
 diminished the numbers of the people, many houses produced 
 no rent®^'. 
 
 The only precise statement which we possess on the subject 
 of house-rent, occurs in Iseeus®'^ ; according to whom a house 
 at Melite worth 30 minas, and another at Eleusis worth 5 
 minas, together produced 3 minas a year, that is 8f per cent.; 
 which is low as compared with the rate of interest, and perhaps 
 ought not to be taken as the general average, as Salmasius 
 supposed®'*. The rent of land must be less than the interest of 
 
 Corona, and the examples there quoted 
 by Taylor, the Decree of the Chaleians 
 in Bceotia in Boeckh. Corp. Inseript. 
 No. 1567, also another Byzantine De- 
 cree in Gniter p. ccccxix. 2, and the 
 Decree of the Thebans, Boeckh. Corp. 
 Inseript. No. 1565. 
 
 ^^^ Ammonius, Harpocration, Pilo- 
 ting, and Hesychius in v. vavKkqpos^ 
 together with the Commentators, also 
 Kuhn ad PoU. 1, 74. 
 
 ^^» Casaub. ad Theophrast. Char. 10. 
 
 ®^^ Ammonius and Thomas M. in v. 
 TTpvTavciov. 
 
 ««« Lys. cont. Erastosth. p. 395. j «'» CEcon. .3, 1. 
 
 Comp. also the passage in Plato, ^"''^ Xenoph. Mem. Socrat. ii. 7, 2. 
 
 although it is not quite decisive, de j ®^^ De Hagn. Hered. p. 293. 
 
 Rep. i. p. 328, B. 1 ®^' De M. U. xix. p. 848.
 
 142 
 
 RENT OF LAND 
 
 [bk. 
 
 the capital vested in it, if this were lent out ; it is also ex- 
 pressly remarked, that in the good old times lands were let to 
 the poor at a moderate rent'^' : according to Isceus'^% an estate 
 in Thria, worth 150 minas, was let for 12 rainas, i.e. at only 
 8 per cent. 
 
 Of the letting of slaves, especially together with the mines, 
 I have treated above ; the exact percentage cannot however be 
 determined ; for although in the speech of Demosthenes against 
 Panteenetus'^% a mine purchased for 60 minas with 30 slaves, 
 reckoned at 105 minas, was let for 105 drachmas a month, yet 
 nothing can be concluded from this fact, as the agreement of 
 rent was only a form, and in reality the tenant was the pro- 
 prietor, and the rent 12 per cent, interest for money lent upon 
 the mine and slaves. 
 
 The account that Phormion paid 160 minas a year for the 
 rent of Pasion's banking-shop, besides the tenant having to 
 maintain tvro children of the proprietor's who were left be- 
 hind, is very unintelhgible"^; who, says ApoUodorus, would 
 give so much for the wooden furniture, the space, and the 
 books? Pasion himself only made 100 minas a year by his 
 banking-shop. This statement indeed occurs in the lease^'% 
 although this document is not sufficiently authenticated : if 
 the rent was so considerable, we must suppose with ApoUodorus, 
 that Pasion at the same time transferred to Phormion some 
 money, which was vested in the concern. Afterwards the 
 banking-shop without the money employed in it was let for 
 a talent"^', in which case the tenant must have still obtained a 
 high profit by trading with borrowed money, which was lent to 
 Pasion's house on account of the credit which it possessed. 
 
 A considerable profit was obtained by the proprietor, if we 
 may credit Demosthenes, by the lease of the house {fila-dayaLs 
 otKov), that is, of the whole property^^% which produced much 
 
 ®^* Isocrat. Areopag. 12. 
 675 Ibid. 
 «76 p. 967. 
 
 «77 Demosth. pro Phorni. p. 956, 6 
 p. 960, 10. 
 
 ^'^s Demosth. c. Steph. i. p. 1111 
 
 and concerning the suspiciousness of 
 the document, p. 1110, 18. 
 
 ^7^ Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 956, 10 ; 
 p. 948, 15. 
 
 ^^" Concerning the meaning of the 
 word oiKos see Xenoph. CEcon. i. 4, 5.
 
 CH. XXIV.] 
 
 AND HOUSES IX ATTICA. 
 
 143 
 
 more than 12 per cent., and by which families worth 2 or 3 
 talents often doubled or trebled their means. Thus the pro- 
 perty of Antidorus, which had been let to one Theogenes, rose 
 in six years from 3^ to 6 talents^^'. In this manner the Archon 
 Eponymus, in conjunction with the guardians, was bound to 
 let the property of orphans, or a Phasis could be instituted 
 against him ; and for the sake of security, the tenant was 
 obliged to give a pledge {aTroTLfiTjfjuaY^^, 
 
 «8^ Demosth. c. Aphob. i. 831, 26 
 sqq. p. 833, 22 sqq. c. Apliob. -^evdo- 
 fxapr. p. 862, 21. 
 
 ^«^ Lys. c. Diogit. p. 906, extr. 
 Isaeus de Philoctem. Hered. p. 141. 
 Demosth. c. Aphob. in the above- 
 quoted passages, Harpocration in v. 
 dTTOTifMTjTal, and his commentators ; 
 
 Hesychius in v. dTroTifxrifiaTa, Pollux 
 viii. 142, and 89, with the commenta- 
 tors. Cf. Herald. Animad. in Salmas. 
 Obs. ad I. A. et R. iii. 6, 5 sqq. Con- 
 cerning the Phasis see Poll. viii. 47, 
 the Epitome of Harpocration, Etymol. 
 Phot. Suid. and Le:^. Seg. pp. 313, 
 315.
 
 144 
 
 Note [A], pp, 16, 20. 
 
 In the SOtli and 6Ctli notes to the first book, the Author refers to his Com- 
 mentary on an Inscription published in the Appendix to the original edition, 
 and since repeated in his Collection of Inscriptions (i. p. 164); where he has 
 added only a short abstract of his former explanation, and therefore it appeared 
 desirable to give in this place a translation of the passage referred to. 
 
 The following extract from the inscription is all that is required. 
 
 'A-y/rcoSe Koi fj fxva t; e[fi]7rop[iK]^ ^T€[(f}avT](p6pov dpax]lJ-as cKarov rpiaKOvra 
 K[a\ j OKTO) 7rp6[s] TO. o-TiiBfjLia TO, [e]i/ rw dpyvpoK07r[€ia. K]a\ [ex^ro) po7rr}]v 
 ['2T€](f>ain](})6pov 8paxp.as Sfxa 8vo, Koi 7ra)Xe[iT]a)o-ai/ Trdvres rdWa [7r]dvTa 
 Tav[TT)] rfj pLva, [ttX^i/] ocra npos dpyvpiov Biapprjdrjv etprjTai n[<i>]\e'LV, la-Tdvres 
 rov 7Tr)-)(yv Tov ^vy\ov la-oplponov, dyovra tcis eKarov TrevTrjKovra ^rpl^xt/^"!^ '^°^ 
 2[Te(PavT](f)]6povt to 8e Trevrdfiuovv [to €pn]optK6v e;j(€V[co p07r'\r]u e^TTopiKTjV 
 fivd[v], o[7r'\a>s laopponov tov 7rf)xea>s yivop.ivov ayrj €p.7rop[iKds p.^vds e^. to de 
 rdikaPTOv to €[fi]7ropiK6p [e;)(eV]a) po7r[fjv fx]v[ds] €p.n[o']piKds TreVre, ottcos koi 
 tov[to lcr]opp67rov tov 7r[7/;(]eci)s yivofxevov ayrj 6[/x]7ro[pi/c]6i/ Td[Xatrrop Kai 
 
 fllvds ifXTTOpiKCLS 7T€VT€. 
 
 *' In this clause it is ordered that the commercial weight should be greater 
 than the common weight ; and that the commercial mina should in the first 
 place be equal to 138 drachmas tov aTe(pav7](p6pov, according to the weights in 
 the silver mint (dpyvpoKovelovy Pollux vii. 103, Harpocration, Suidas, and 
 other grammarians'), and secondly, that it should contain 12 additional drach- 
 mas TOV o-Tc(f)apTj(f)6pov, so that the whole would amount to 150 drachmas. 
 Here we are met with questions which do not admit of an easy solution. In 
 the fii"st place, what is 2Te(f)apr)(f)6pos ? 2Tecf)apr](f)6pos was a hero at Athens, 
 and had a rjpaop, but the grammarians have not themselves any accurate 
 knowledge concernmg liim. See Harpocration, Photius, and Suidas in 
 2T€(f)avTi(f)6pos, Lex. Seg. p. 301, Meurs. Lect. Att. iv. 10. Compare Sturz 
 Fragment. Hellan. p. 59. The Tjpwop was doubtless the same as the house 
 which was called 2T€(j)apT](ji6pov (not ^T€(papr)(f)6pos), although the gloss of 
 Hesychius is rather obscm*e : ^Tecpapop (pupeoPTa' dir oIkov tipos KoXovfiepov 
 (rT€(papT)(f)6pov. The contrary opinion of Meursius on this point must be 
 attributed to mere inadvertency. This rjpSop was mentioned by Antiphon 
 against Nicocles quoted in Harpocration, Photius, and Suidas : 2T€cf)apr)(f)6pos' 
 'ApTt({ia>p €P ro) npos Nt/coKXea* "STecfiaprjcpopov rjpatop, cos coiKep, r/p eV Toli 
 'ABripais. Now in the same speech the silver mint was mentioned, according 
 to Harpocration : 'ApyvpoKOTrelop' 'ApTi(f)cop ip rw rrpos NikokXco, &c. Can it 
 be doubted that in Antiphon, as well as in the present inscription, Stephane- 
 phorus occurred in connexion with the silver mint ? I conjecture therefore 
 that at Athens the mint was combined with a chapel of this hero, as in Rome 
 witli the temple of Juno Moneta ; that the standard weights for coin were kept 
 in this sanctuary, which belonged to the chief mint, as at Rome they were 
 preserved in the temple of Juno Moneta ; and that from this circumstance the 
 drachmas of the weight used for silver were called diachmas roi'- '2Tccf>ctpr^(jmpov.
 
 NOTE TO BOOK I. l45 
 
 As however it is fixed that the commercial mina should contain 138 
 drachmas tov 2T€(f>aur](f)6poVf to which were to be farther added 12 
 drachmas of the same weight, it is at once evident, from the adoption of 
 so irregular a number as 138, that this could not have been a new or arbitrary 
 arrangement, but that it must have proceeded upon some ancient regulations 
 with regard to the common and the mint weights. Our object is now to 
 ascertain in what this dissimilarity consisted. It is well known that Solon 
 diminished the weight of the coin ; his intention being to favour the debtors, 
 by enabling them to repay their debts in a depreciated currency. The mina, 
 as well before as after the time of Solon, manifestly contained 100 drachmas : 
 but 100 drachmas, before Solon interfered with the currency, were heavier 
 than after. Plutarch affirms that Solon increased the measures at the same 
 time that he diminished the weight of the coin : this however is absurd ; for by 
 this means the proprietors of mortgaged land would have received no possible 
 benefit ; they would rather have experienced a loss, if they exchanged at the 
 old price a larger measure of products of the soil against a smaller weight of 
 coin; nor can Solon be well supposed to have had any other motive than this 
 in increasing the measures. If there is any meaning in Plutarch's statementj 
 he can only wish to express a proportional increase in the weights, i. e. that 
 while the weight for money was reduced, the weights for commodities remained 
 the same. 
 
 This view of the subject is peculiarly fitted to explain the present inscrip- 
 tion. The weight univereally used in Athens before the time of Solon, as 
 well for silver as for other commodities, was such, that 138 of the new 
 drachmas were equal to a mina. SjIou allowed this weight to remain for all 
 uses of trade, but made the coin so much lighter, that the mina of silver was 
 to the commercial mina as 100 to 138. It is now easy to perceive why late 
 wi-iters, being deceived by this ratio, supposed the weight to have been 
 increased; for after this change the commercial mina weighed 138 drachmas, 
 having before only weighed 100 : but it was only in comparison with silver, 
 and not absolutely, that it had sustained an increase. Upon this supposition 
 the new silver mina of Solon was equal to 72 1| ancient drachmas; for 
 100 : 138 : : 72|| : 100. It is not however possible that Solon could have 
 purposely introduced such a proportion ; probably he had intended to diminish 
 the weight of the coin by a fourth part, so that 75 old drachmas were to be 
 coined into 100 new : the money however (for at that time coined money was 
 doubtless in use) proved in fact to be not sufficiently heavy; and it was 
 observed that 100 of the new di"achmas were only equal to 72 1| of the old; or, 
 what is the same thing, 100 of the old to 138 of the new; accordingly the i-atio 
 between the commercial mina and the new silver mina was fixed at 138 to 100, 
 not, as it would have been according to the ratio originally intended, at 133| 
 to 100. 
 
 Thus far everything appears to be a mere assumption, made for the purpose 
 of explaining the mode of fixing the commercial mina made use of in the 
 present decree; but the following testimony gives it the authority of an histo- 
 rical fact. Plutarch (Solon, 15) informs us that Solon made the mina of 100 
 drachmas, whereas it had previously contained 73, by wliicli change the value 
 of money was diminished; cKaruv yap inolT)a€ 8paxpoi)v rijv p.vav, nporepou 
 €^bop.T)KovTa KoX rpiojv ovcraVy coot' apt^/xai pev XaoVy dvpdpei fi' fXarrov dncdi- 
 dovTCiv <o(f)e\('i(Tdat pev rovs (ktivovtus pcyaXaj pr)bev he ^XdnreaOai rovs 
 Kopi(opevovs. It will at first sight be perceived, that Plutarch here expresses 
 
 L,
 
 146 NOTE TO BOOK I. 
 
 liimself ambiguously. What relief could it have been to debtors who owed 
 several minas, that the division of the mina was altered, and the drachma 
 diminished, while the mina itself remained the same? And again, can it be 
 believed that the mina contained 73 drachmas, a prime number, not divisible 
 without a remainder ? Plutarch follows Androtion, who had doubtless stated that 
 a weight of silver, which before Solon had only been equal to 73 drachmas, had 
 been coined by Solon into a mina, or 100 drachmas. This statement so nearly 
 agrees with the view before taken, that the coincidence cannot be the result of 
 chance. Both statements differ only by the fraction of a drachma ; the number 
 obtained from the decree is however doubtless the more correct one, and the 
 other is only an approximation. The following circumstance should also be 
 observed. The Euboic talent was to the Attic talent of Solon as 72 to 70, 
 which is the same as 75 to 12\^. If we assume that this ratio is not strictly 
 accurate, but that the correct one is 75 to 72 1|, or, what is the same, 72 /© to 
 70, the ancient Attic talent, before the change of Solon, was to the Euboic as 
 100 to 75, and Solon, in his diminution of the weight for silver, intended to 
 introduce the Euboic standard, without however entirely accomplishing his 
 object."
 
 147 
 
 BOOK II. 
 
 ON THE FINANCIAL ADMINISTRATION AND EXPENDITURE 
 OF THE ATHENIAN STATE. 
 
 Chapter I. 
 
 7%e Comparative Importance of the Financial Management in 
 Ancient and Modern States, 
 
 The preceding enquiries having opened the way for the pur- 
 suance of the main subject of this work, the first question which 
 arrests our attention is^ whether in ancient times the operation 
 of the financial system was of the same general and predomi- 
 nant importance, and exercised that influence upon the welfare 
 and decHne of nations, which it possesses in modern days. 
 Hegewisch^ first expressed his astonishment that in the states 
 of antiquity, revolutions had been so seldom caused by taxation 
 and financial regulations, which have been the chief sources of 
 disturbance among modern nations. A later writer has ac- 
 counted for this diflerence by stating that in ancient times the 
 civil and judicial constitution was the principal cause of revolu- 
 tions, whereas in modern times these have resulted chiefly from 
 the system of finance*. It is indeed true that in the democra- 
 cies of antiquity a revolution could scarcely arise from a refusal 
 to pay taxes; and in the states of Greece, at its most flourish- 
 
 ^ Historischer Versuch iiber die Rd- 
 mischen Finanzen, p. 44 sqq. 
 
 ^ Wagemann de quibusdam causis, 
 ex qviibus turn in veteribus turn in re- 
 centiorum civitatibus turbae ortse sunt, 
 aut status reipublicse immutatus est, 
 Heidelberg. 1810, 4to. [It may, how- 
 ever, be remarked, that Aristotle men- 
 
 tions in his Politics that some persons 
 considered the distribution of property 
 as the main cause of revolutions in the 
 Greek states : So/cei tktl to nepl ras 
 ovaias elvai fieytarov Teraxdai KaXa>s' 
 Trepl yap Tovrtov iroKlcrOai <f>a<Ti ras 
 (TTciaeis navras. ii. 4.— Transl.] 
 
 L 2
 
 148 FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT IN [bK. II. 
 
 ing period, democracy was the prevailing form of government. 
 In this form of polity, the iniposers and payers of taxes are in 
 fact the same persons: whence then was there a possibility of 
 dissension between the two classes? Besides, in a democracy 
 the people never apply the public money to objects which are 
 opposed either to their real or apparent interests, which is not 
 unlikely to happen under an aristocratic or despotic form of 
 government. If then discontent was at any time excited 
 amongst particular individuals by the financial measures of the 
 state, the majority of the citizens concurred in and supported 
 them, they themselves having been the very persons with whom 
 they originated. That an insurrection should arise from this 
 cause was consequently as improbable as that popular commo- 
 tions should be caused at Athens by a summons to war. The 
 chief sources of disturbance must have been created by en- 
 croachments upon the rights of the citizens, especially with 
 respect to their share in the governing power; whereas in the 
 monarchies of modern times, the people being for the most part 
 indifferent as to who fills the office of king, only feel themselves 
 oppressed by those who obstruct them in the enjoyment of 
 their property, and diminish their means of subsistence by the 
 imposition of taxes and by other compulsory measures; except- 
 ing that at particular periods, when the sense of the nation has 
 been more generally excited, the people have pressed for an 
 ampler recognition of their rights. In those ancient states 
 which were not democracies, the government, especially that of 
 tyrants, was indeed generally odious from the burthens with 
 which it oppressed the people, but still more so on account of 
 the loss of freedom. These two causes together produced num- 
 berless revolutions. 
 
 It should however be borne in mind, that in the republican 
 states, the attention paid to the public finances was by no 
 means so inconsiderable as some writers have imagined; wealth 
 was not less an object of desire at that than at the present 
 time ; the exigencies of the state were, comparatively speaking, 
 not fewer than in modern Europe, at least as far as Athens is 
 concerned; although the objects to which the expenditure was 
 directed, and the means of extricating the state from an unfore-
 
 CH. I.] ANCIENT AND MODERN STATES. 149 
 
 seen pressure, differed in many points, with the difference in 
 the political circumstances, from the corresponding practices in 
 modern days. The ancients, for reasons which we shall after- 
 wards explain, had no artificial public system of finance; but 
 the exigencies of the state were not on that account less press- 
 ing upon individuals. If at the present day any additional 
 taxes were required for the purpose of paying off the national 
 debt, the payers of taxes would not be called upon at a period 
 of urgent necessity ; and the sum, which at the precise moment 
 of need could only be raised in full to the great inconvenience 
 of the taxed, would wath moderate interest be paid off in a 
 series of years: whereas, according to the usual practice in 
 ancient times, the expenses of the commonwealth were imme- 
 diately defrayed by the payers of taxes, and a part of their 
 capital was sacrificed, which might have been turned with profit 
 to fresh production. So that the want of a public system of 
 finance was rather injurious than otherwise to the citizens of 
 the ancient states, and the administration of finance more 
 oppressive. 
 
 Nor can it be inferred that this branch of the administra- 
 tion was held in low esteem at Athens, from the circumstance 
 that no archon was placed at the head of it; for the influence of 
 the archons even in early times had become very inconsiderable. 
 But in every Greek state the finances were in the hands of the 
 sovereign power; and at Athens the legislation on financial 
 matters belonged to the people, the administration of them to 
 the supreme council. Then, as well as now, the administration 
 of the finances was considered one of the most important 
 branches of public affairs; and the statesman who, like Aristides 
 and Lycurgus, succeeded in placing them in a flourishing con- 
 dition, gained the goodwill of the people and the admiration of 
 posterity. Some statesmen in the ancient days of Greece even 
 occupied themselves exclusively with this branch of the admi- 
 nistration^; and all the great demagogues endeavoured to obtain 
 over it either a direct or an indirect influence, since the manage- 
 ment of the public money afforded both the most effectual 
 
 3 Aristot. Polit. i. 7,(11.)
 
 150 
 
 FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT IN [bK. I 
 
 means of advancing themselves into favour with the people and 
 of maintaining that position. Thus Eubulus of Anaphlystus% 
 who applied himself in particular to financial affairs, obtained a 
 lasting popularity, although it was chiefly acquired by flattering 
 the avarice of a pleasure-seeking people, through the distribu- 
 tion and lavish expenditure of the public money. In Athens, 
 the ministers of finance would have been held in as high esteem 
 as in modern states, if all measures of general pohcy had not 
 been deliberated on and decided by the mass of the people; 
 notv\dthstanding which the chief manager of the public revenue 
 was always looked up to as one of the most important public 
 officers. In the progress of time the faulty management of the 
 finances of Athens essentially contributed to the destruction of 
 the state, more especially from the period when she was forced 
 to defend herself from foreign attack. If the powers of the 
 government are misdirected, the moral condition of a state can- 
 not alone preserve it. Immoderate exertions and excesses 
 equally render a state and an individual incapable of performing 
 their proper functions. Now Athens overstrained both her 
 mental and physical powers (of which the power arising from 
 wealth is not the least), partly in great and noble exertions, 
 partly in vain and profligate waste; after w^hich she naturally 
 fell into such a state of weakness and inactivity, as to be unable 
 to resist the first violent pressure to which she might be ex- 
 posed. Can it then be maintained, that financial regulations 
 were of less importance in ancient than in modern times, or 
 that they had less influence upon the public welfare? Unques- 
 tionably not; provided that the comparison is correctly insti- 
 tuted, and that the distinction is kept in view which is caused 
 by the wide dissimilarity between the size of the most remark- 
 able and important states of antiquity, and those of modern 
 Europe. 
 
 J. J. Rousseau^ maintains, that a government becomes more 
 dependent on its finance in proportion as the other energies of 
 
 Plutarch. Vrsec. Reip. Ger. 15 ; mens de I'ine'galit^ parmi les hommes, 
 
 cf. iEschin. c. Ctcsiph. p. 417. 
 
 * Discours sur rorigine et les foude- 
 
 p. 314. Geneva, 1782, vol. i. of his 
 works.
 
 CH. I.J ANCIENT AND MODERN STATES. 151 
 
 the people decline, and that a state may be considered as having 
 arrived at the last stage of corruption, when it has no other 
 power than that which is derived from its wealth. In this 
 manner, he thinks, all governments tend incessantly to decay, 
 and consequently that no state can endure, if its revenues are 
 not perpetually increasing. Although these remarks may not 
 be wholly correct in the extended sense in which he applies 
 them, they are still supported by a large majority of facts; and 
 it is certain that as long as the early vigour of the human mind 
 is still unimpaired, the state is far less in need of those artifi- 
 cial arrangements which are necessary for the levying of money 
 from the people. For as soon as the pressure of any immediate 
 and urgent necessity excites the citizens, they spare no sacrifice 
 or exertion to satisfy the exigency. This was the case with 
 respect to Athens before the administration of Pericles, and 
 particularly before the Peloponnesian war, at which time a 
 great change in the Athenian character took place. Their 
 oppression of the allies, and the consequent employment of 
 mercenaries, taught the Athenians to place greater reliance upon 
 the assistance of foreigners, than upon their own exertions ; the 
 poison, however, operated slowly, because the feelings of honour 
 with which the overthrow of the barbarians and the liberation 
 of their common country had inspired them, were not as yet 
 obliterated ; while ambition still in some degree supplied the 
 place of purer motives, and the fear of a momentary sacrifice 
 was overcome by the hope of the ample compensation which 
 would probably follow in the train of victory. It is certain that 
 after the age of Pericles the administration of the finances 
 became of greater importance, and that the expenses of the 
 state increased, as public principle declined. Athens, however, 
 by the augmentation of the tribute received from her allies, as 
 well as by the imposition of customs and other duties, found 
 the means of increasing her revenues. By these means she 
 succeeded in maintaining hei;self, notwithstanding her many 
 reverses and defeats, until not only her moral strength had 
 almost expired, but her revenues also had greatly diminished. 
 Then it was that she became powerless and lost her inde- 
 pendence.
 
 152 FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT. [bK. IT. 
 
 Rousseau infers from the principles above laid down^ that 
 the first maxim of financial administration is to restrain as much 
 as possible the tendency to expense, and to exert the utmost 
 vigilance in order to anticipate the appearance of any want. 
 He thinks that in spite of every care, the remedy will always be 
 too late for the disease, and the state will thus be left in a suf- 
 fering condition; that at the moment when one expense is 
 about to be retrenched, another arises; that additional re- 
 sources are themselves productive of new difficulties, the people 
 become oppressed, the government loses all its strength, and 
 notwithstanding its great expenditure, is able to effect little. 
 Rousseau is of opinion that by these principles we may account 
 for the almost miraculous phenomenon of the ancient govern- 
 ments having been enabled to effect more with their frugality than 
 modern states can perform with all their riches. I quote this 
 remark with a view to caution the reader against applying it to 
 Athens, where after the time of Pericles, expense was heaped 
 upon expense, the administration of finance became continually 
 of more importance, and the difficulties continually greater. It 
 also throws a strong light upon the public salaries at Athens; 
 although these resulted in part from other circumstances, such 
 as the poverty of the citizens, and the pretensions which the 
 state would not consent to abandon, though unable to satisfy 
 them from its own resources. This increase in the expenses of 
 the community far above the measure of its strength, rendered 
 an attention to the affairs of finance more necessary to the 
 Athenians than to any other Grecian state. 
 
 Chapter II. 
 
 Subject of the Second, Third, and Fourth Books, stated. 
 
 To obtain a knowledge of the financial system of Athens in its 
 whole extent, we must consider how it was administered, what 
 were the exigencies of the state, and what revenues there were 
 to meet them, and whether the latter were in general sufficient, 
 or whether at times tliey produced a surplus, and what extraor- 
 dinary resources were available un the appearance of difficulties.
 
 CII. II.] SUBJECT OF THE ENSUING BOOKS STATED. 153 
 
 We here limit ourselves to the economy of the state alone, 
 excluding subordinate companies and corporations; although, 
 as Athens was both a city and a state, many things must be 
 included in the public finances, which in larger nations would 
 only belong to corporate bodies; and again, many parts of the 
 finances of subordinate communities were so intimately con- 
 nected with the state, that on that account they ought not to 
 be passed over. The expenses of the temples and sacred cor- 
 porations were partly defrayed from revenues of their own, 
 which were independent of the state, and thus far they will not 
 be treated of in this book; but in so far as the state advanced 
 contributions, or availed itself of the sacred revenues and 
 treasures in pecuniary difficulties, upon the condition of restor- 
 ing them% the finances of the state and of the sacred institutions 
 are linked together, and the latter therefore deserve at least an 
 occasional consideration. 
 
 Chapter III. 
 
 Supreme Authorities for the Financial Administration; the 
 People and the Senate. Subordinate Authorities, 
 
 The legislative authority in matters of finance, as in all other 
 things, belonged to the people, as being sovereign [Kvpuos), 
 All the regular expenses and revenues were determined by the 
 laws which it enacted, and every extraordinary measure received 
 its authority by a decree of the people. But the administration 
 was entrusted to the Senate of 500, as the agents of the com- 
 munity, who were responsible to the people: this council pre- 
 pared questions in debate for the popular assembly, and had 
 the different branches of the public economy under its superin- 
 tendence. That the power of the senate with reference to mat- 
 ters of finance was as extensive as here represented, is evident 
 from the following examples. According to Xenophon^s Trea- 
 tise upon the Athenian republic^, the senate was occupied with 
 
 ^ Cf. e. g. Thiicyd. ii. 13 ; vi. 8. ^ 3^ o See Petit, Leg. Att. ii. I,
 
 iSi SUPREME AND SUBORDINATE AUTHORITIES j^BK. II, 
 
 providing moneys, with receiving the tribute, and with the 
 management of naval affairs and of the temples. The letting of 
 the duties was under its superintendence. Those who had 
 received sacred or public monies from the state were bound to 
 pay them to the senate, or it enforced the payment of them 
 according to the laws relating to the farming of duties^: it had 
 therefore the right of sending the farmers or their securities to 
 prison in case of non-payment^ The Apodectee delivered to 
 this body an account of the monies received and still remaining 
 due; in the presence of this council the treasurers of the god- 
 dess transferred and accepted the treasures, and received the 
 fines. The senate arranged also the application of the public 
 money even in trifling matters, such for example as the salary 
 of the poets : the superintendence of the cavalry maintained by 
 the state, and the examination of the infirm {dBvvaroL) sup- 
 ported at the public cost, are particularly mentioned among its 
 duties: the public debts were also paid under its direction^". 
 From this enumeration we are justified in inferring that all 
 questions of finance were confided to its supreme direction. It 
 is possible that in early times the Areopagus, which was of so 
 great importance before its power was diminished by Ephialtes, 
 also exercised some authority in affairs of finance. For in the 
 Persian war this tribunal once directed that every person bear- 
 ing arms or serving in the fleet should receive eight drachmas 
 from the Areopagites^' (by which public, and not private, money 
 is meant), whence it might be concluded, that the authority 
 of this supreme office of government extended to financial 
 matters. 
 
 The officers subordinate to the senate, by whom the ma- 
 chinery of finance was worked, may be classed under three 
 heads: in the first place, those who made the arrangements 
 
 8 Demosth. c. Timocr. p. 730. ] another inscription (No. 80, ibid.), 
 
 » See the Oath in Petit iii. 12, 2; but in what particular relation is not 
 
 cf. 10. 
 
 '" Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 76. 
 The senate also is mentioned in con- 
 nection with the sacred money in j 
 
 stated. 
 
 '^ Plutarch. Themist. 10, from Aris- 
 totle.
 
 CH. 111.] FOR FINANCIAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 sl56 
 
 and preparations necessary for the collection of the revenue, or 
 collected it themselves; secondly, the treasurers of the offices 
 into which the revenues were paid, in which they were kept, 
 and where they were again disbursed; and thirdly, those whose 
 duty it was to discharge the accounts. Concerning the first 
 division it will be unnecessary to say much, as in treating of 
 •the revenue the method of its collection must be in part con- 
 sidered. All regular duties were let to farmers {reXcovai,); for 
 these imposts therefore no particular places of payment were 
 necessary, except for receiving the money from the farmers; an 
 office was how^ever required to arrange the letting, or (as the 
 ancients term it) the sale of the duties. Now every thing that 
 the state sold or farmed out, taxes, lands, mines, confiscated 
 property, (including the property of public debtors after the 
 expiration of the last term,) the persons of resident aliens who 
 had not paid their protection money, and foreigners who had 
 been guilty of illegally assuming the rights of citizenship or of 
 the offence of Apostasion; all these duties were left to the care 
 of the ten Pole tee, a board {apxv)} to which each tribe contri- 
 buted one member, and which met at a place called Poleterion'*. 
 Among them was a Prytaneus, who presided; for the sale of 
 the duties they were allowed the assistance of the directors of 
 the Theoricon*^; but they managed everything in the name and 
 under the authority of the senate alone, for which reason in the 
 sale of the fiftieth and of the tax upon prostitutes we read of 
 the co-operation of the senate'*. The property of the temples 
 was however let by the directors of sacred property, as may be 
 inferred from the Sandwich inscription, in which the Amphic- 
 tyons of Delos render an account of the leases; the property of 
 the tribes and boroughs was let by themselves through their 
 own agent or manager, to whom the payments were also made'^ 
 
 '* Aristot. de Rep. Athen. ap. Har- 
 pocr. in v. TraiXrjTai, Suidas in vv. 
 TTotXTjTol and naiXrjTrj^, Phot, in v. 
 7rco\r)Ta\ (twice), Hesych. and Lex. 
 Seg. p. 201,: Pollux viii 99; Ilaipocr. 
 in V. nfToiKiov; Demosth. c. Aiistogit. 
 j. p. 787 ; cf. Petit, ii. 5, 2. The ex- j bulid. p. 1318, 18. 
 
 planation in Lex. Seg. p. 192, 21, is 
 incorrect. 
 
 ^^ Pollux viii. 99. 
 
 ^* See book iii. c. 4 and 7. 
 
 ^^ See Boeckh, Inscript. 158, 103, 
 104, book iii. c. 2: Demosth. c. Eu-
 
 156 
 
 SUBORDINATE AUTHORITIES 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 Another class of the public revenues consisted of the justice- 
 fees and fines; these were registered by the presidents of the 
 court of justice which had decided the cause, when the part that 
 accrued to the state was paid over to the officers named ex- 
 actors {TTpaKTOpes), and the portion which was allotted to any 
 god was placed in the hands of the treasurers of the proper 
 temple, who either received the money or annulled the judg- 
 ment". Certain fines were registered by the king-archon'% 
 doubtless in his capacity of head of the court of justice. When 
 the payment had been made, the names were erased by the 
 officers whose duty it was to exact the money, for example, the 
 practores, together with the senate' ^ The tributes of the 
 alhes were probably paid without the immediate interference of 
 the Athenian state; yet in this case also it was sometimes 
 necessary to appoint certain temporary authorities, such as the 
 officers who fixed the sum to be paid by the subject state 
 {i7ri'ypa(f)€i9Y^, and others who collected the tribute, if it had 
 fallen into arrear {eKXoyeU) ; the latter, however, were chosen 
 from among the rich, nor can theirs be considered as a perma- 
 nent situation more than the former, as they are only mentioned 
 in a fragment of Antiphon concerning the tribute of the Samo- 
 thracians^". As the Spartans had their harmosts, so had the 
 Athenians officers named episcopi (eTr/cr/coTrot, <f>v\aK€s) as 
 inspectors in the tributary states; Antiphon had mentioned 
 them in his oration concerning the tribute of the Lindians**, 
 but we are not informed whether they were in any way con- 
 cerned with the collection of the tributes. Each tribe was 
 
 '^ Lysias irrrep rov aTpaTt.ci)Tov, p. 
 323, 324 ; Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1074, 
 sqq.; Andoc. de Myst. p. 36; ^schin. 
 c. Timarch. p. 62, 63 ; Orat. c. Theo- 
 crin. p. 1327, 29; p. 1337, 26; De- 
 mosth. c. Aristog. i. p. 778, 18. [The 
 authors of the Attische Process, p. 32, 
 observe, that " this last assertion must 
 be limited to the fines summarily im- 
 posed by the magisti-ates {inL^oKai) ; 
 for no public officer had power either 
 to mitigate or remit a penalty decreed 
 by a comt of justice." — Thansl.] 
 
 '7 Andoc. de Myst. p. 37. 
 
 ^^ Andoc. ut sup. p. 38. 
 
 ^^ See below, note 23. 
 
 ^^ In Harpocr. and Suidas. "Whe- 
 ther these are the same as the eicXoyeis' 
 appointed by lot like the practores, 
 who are mentioned in Lex. Seg. p. 
 190, 26, or diiferent officers are meant, 
 is not certain : probably the passage 
 in this Lexicon refers to all exXo-yetj. 
 
 2' Cf. Schol. Arist. Av. 102:i. Har- 
 pocr. in V, (rrio-KOTToi, and see b. iii^ 
 ch. 16.
 
 CH. III.] FOR FINANCIAL ADMINISTRATION. 
 
 167 
 
 bound to take care that the regular public services {XeiTovpytai) 
 were correctly performed by the citizens: which inspection 
 therefore fell within the department of the head managers of 
 the tribes [eirtiMeXriral rcov <f>v\(i)v), to whom this duty, as well 
 as that of administering the funds of the tribes, is attributed by 
 ancient writers". The superintendence and allotment of the 
 trierarchy was divided between certain authorities, who will be 
 pointed out in a subsequent part of this work, and the chief 
 managers of the companies appointed for its direction, who in 
 ancient times were doubtless the naucrari, and subsequently the 
 managers of the Symmorise {eTnfjLeXrjral rwv av/Mfiopcwv) . For the 
 extraordinary property tax {el<T(f>opa), certain persons were nomi- 
 nated, in order to determine the amount of the contributions, who, 
 as well as the officers who fixed the rate of the tributes of the 
 allies, were called i'irtypa(f)€i9 or hLaypa<^eis, and were probably 
 ten in number; these officers also prosecuted those who were 
 in arrear'\ Besides these authorities, the directors of the Sym- 
 morise, from the time that this establishment was connected 
 with the property taxes, must have had the chief management 
 of the distribution. Certain persons were also employed as 
 collectors**. Lastly, the demarchs must have been highly ser- 
 viceable in all affairs connected with these taxes, as, before the 
 institution of their office, were the naucrari, since they were able 
 to aiFord the best information concerning the property of the 
 inhabitants^\ We are indeed told that the demarchs collected 
 pubhc money from the citizens*^ which might only mean that 
 they enforced the claims which a borough in its corporate capa- 
 city had upon its members or upon a tenant renting some of 
 its property; it may however be safely allowed that they were 
 employed for various debts and dues claimed by the state*'. 
 
 ** See Sigon. de Rep. Athen. iv. 2. 
 
 ^ Harpocrat. in vv. eTnypaffiels, 6ia- 
 ypanixa ; Suidas in different places, in 
 vv. €7riypa<p€7st fita-ypac^eiy, bidypapma, 
 and eniyvcopLoves ; EtjTnol. in vv. ein- 
 •ypa^cTs and eTriyvco/xoi/e?. Lex. Seg. 
 p. 254; Pollux viii. 103; Isocr. Tra- 
 pez. 21 ; of. Sigon. R. A. iv. 3. 
 
 ^* Suid. in v. eKXoyeT?. Tliese are 
 
 the officers alluded to in Demosth. c. 
 Polycl. p. 1209, 9. 
 
 25 Pollux viii. 108. 
 
 2^ Demosth. c. Eubul. ut sup. Con- 
 cerning the Naucrari in this point of 
 view, see book iii. ch. 2. 
 
 *7 An example, although not satis- 
 factory, may be seen in Boeckh, In- 
 script. 80.
 
 158 
 
 FIX A X CI A L A DM I X ISTR ATI OX. 
 
 [bk, 
 
 The senate and tlie people on particular occasions appointed 
 certain persons for the collection of the outstanding property- 
 taxes, a duty for which Androtion and nine others were 
 once selected". In like manner the syndics {avvScKot), who 
 were introduced after the dominion of the Thirty Tyrants, were 
 authorities nominated for the moment, being revenue law- 
 officers of the state, who decided upon confiscated property*'; 
 the o-vWoyeU, who made a list of the property of the oligarchs 
 previously to its confiscation^"; the ^r,TT)Tal, a revenue-board 
 which was at times appointed to ascertain who were indebted 
 to the public, particularly with regard to fraud and conceal- 
 ment^'. The same name however was applied also to persons 
 who were entrusted by the state on certain occasions with the 
 discovery of other offences^^ These and the practores are 
 reckoned by Pollux^^ among the inferior officers {vTrrjperal); 
 but their office was an office of government {apxv)y which citi- 
 zens of high rank were not ashamed to accept. 
 
 ^^ Demosth. c. Androt. 
 
 ^ Sigon. R. A. iv. 4 ; Petit, iii. 2, 
 31, where Wesselmg quotes from Va- 
 lesiiis upon Harpocration, in v. crvvbiKoi, 
 the decisive passages of Lysias (pro 
 Mantith. p. 574, nepi drjfi. d8iK. p. 597, 
 in Poliuch, p. 613, pro Aristoph. bonis, 
 p. 635). Photius also has transcribed 
 the article of Harpocration in v. avv- 
 di<oi. Cf. Herald. Animadv. in Sal- 
 mas. Observ. iii. 10, 13. 
 
 2" Vid. ad Inscript. 157. 
 
 3^ Sigon. R. A. iv. 3. Hudtwalcker 
 von den Diateten, p. 58, and also De- 
 mosth. c. Timocrat. p. 696, 9; Lex. 
 Seg. p. 261. Both the latter passages 
 are given by Sluiter Lect. Andocid. 
 p. 55. Cf. Phot, in v. CrjTTjTTji. At 
 Pellene they were called fidcrTpoi ; tlie 
 word fj.a(TTr}p€s occurred in Hyperides. 
 
 See Harpocr. Lex. Seg. p. 279. Suid. 
 Phot, in vv. fiacrrripes and fxdcrTdpes. 
 According to the Lex. Seg. and Pho- 
 tius in the first article, it was their 
 duty to examine confiscated property, 
 and they were therefore nearly allied 
 to the avWoyels. I should observe 
 that Hudtwalcker (p. 32) is in my 
 opinion incorrect in only considering 
 the zetetae as an office of government 
 (dpxrj) in the same manner that this 
 title is conferred upon judges, heralds, 
 and clerks ; but I must defer to ano- 
 ther place the explanation of the word 
 dpxrj, and its opposite vTrrjpeo-la, as 
 employed in the political language of 
 Athens. 
 
 3^ Andoc. de Myst. p. 7, 18, 20, 32. 
 
 ^' viii. 114, 115.
 
 en. IV.] THE APODECT/E, OR RECEIVERS. J59 
 
 Chapter IV. 
 
 The Apodectce, or Receivers, 
 
 All the revenues under the care of the preparatory officers 
 were necessarily delivered up to others, who either distributed 
 them for the public service or kept them for security. Aris- 
 totle^"*, in speaking of the officers of government, mentions those 
 to whom the public revenues are paid, as well as others who 
 keep and distribute them to separate branches of the adminis- 
 tration: these are called, he adds, Apodectse and treasurers. 
 At Athens there were ten apodectse, after the number of the 
 tribes, chosen by lot; these were introduced by Cleisthenes in 
 the place of the ancient Colacretse. They kept the lists of all 
 persons who were indebted to the state, received the money 
 which was paid in, made an entry of it, and marked the out- 
 standing sums, erased the names of the debtors from the list in 
 the senate-house in presence of the senate, and returned this 
 register into the archives: and lastly, they together with the 
 senate, distributed the money that had been paid in, that is to 
 say, they assigned it to the separate offices. Their duties were 
 accurately described by Aristotle, in his constitution of Athens. 
 They also had power to decide causes connected wdth the sub- 
 jects under their managements^, a privilege which was allowed 
 to nearly all public officers at Athens. As far as can be ascer- 
 tained from the accounts which are still extant, they received in 
 the presence of the senate all the monies which belonged to the 
 state; but the revenues of the temples and of the small corpo- 
 rations were independent of them: nor had they any funds of 
 their own, but only distributed to the different offices the 
 money that was paid in. If their duties should appear confined, 
 
 ^ Polit. vi. 8. 
 
 ^* Pollux viii. 97. Harpocr. in v. 
 aiTobeKTai from Aristotle and Andro- 
 tion, Suid. Etym. Hesych. Lex. Seg. 
 
 shall not always quote the latter gram- 
 marian, as for the most he only copied 
 other authorities. The apodectse also 
 occur in Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 750, 
 
 p. 198, and Zonaras in v. anobeKrai. I I 24, as persons who were present at the 
 may mention here, once for all, that I j paying in of money.
 
 160 
 
 THE APODECT.E, OR RECEIVERS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 it will not seem surprising that the duty of receiving the tributes 
 of the allies is expressly ascribed to them by Pollux, notwith- 
 standing the hellenotamise appear to have been appointed for that 
 purpose: for although the latter, before the funds of Delos were 
 transferred to Athens and united with the Athenian treasury, 
 had the entire levying and management of the tributes, it was 
 possible for the tributes to have been afterwards received by 
 the apodectee in the senate, and have been then paid into the 
 ofl&ce of the hellenotamiae to defray the expenses which were 
 assigned to their funds. After the abolition of the helleno- 
 tamiae, the apodectee were the only officers who could have 
 received the tributes. The treasurers^® of the tribes and bo- 
 roughs also received and administered the money belonging 
 to these corporations; and in the same manner the revenues 
 which periodically accrued to the sacred corporations, were paid 
 to their own treasurers independently of the apodectae. 
 
 Chapter V. 
 The Treasurer of the Goddess, and of the other Gods, 
 
 Every temple of importance had a treasure which was com- 
 posed of offerings, and of the surplus of the amount of the 
 sacred property, together with other receipts which belonged 
 to the particular deity, and these treasures were under the 
 management of the treasurers of the sacred monies {jaiiiaL rcov 
 lepwv ')(^p7]^dT(i3vy\ The sacred treasure of the greatest magni- 
 tude at Athens was that of Minerva, upon the Acropolis; to 
 which (not to mention in this place the public monies which 
 were deposited there), not only the large amount of sacred 
 offerings and rents^^, many fines without any deduction, and of 
 others a per centage equal to the tenth part, were assigned, but 
 also the tithe of all prizes taken in war, together with that of 
 
 '^ Concerning these officers, see 
 Chandler Inscript. ii. 109, wliere the 
 Tdfxias of a borough, and another in- 
 scription (n, 142, ed. Bocckh,) where 
 
 the TOfxias of a tribe occurs. 
 ^7 Aristot. Poht, vi. 8. 
 ^^ See book iii. c. 12.
 
 CH. v.] TREASURERS OF THE GODDESS AND GODS. 161 
 
 confiscated property^^ Many articles of great value were pre- 
 served in the neighbouring temples, but the chief treasure was 
 deposited in the opisthodomus of the Parthenon'"', ever after 
 the building of that temple. These treasures of the temple of 
 Minerva were under the care of the treasurers of Minerva or 
 of the goddess, who were also called treasurers of the sacred pro- 
 perty of Minerva or of the goddess {rafilat rrjs- Oeov or t(ov 
 rrJ9 6eov, rafjulai, tmv lepMV y^prjfidrayv tyjs ^K9r]vatas^ jajjuiaL 
 rSiv lepcov ^(^pT^fidTtov Trj<^ Beov). The most ancient mention of 
 them, which is in Herodotus*^, refers to the time of the battle 
 of Salamis; in later times they frequently occur as the trea- 
 surers of the monies and property of Minerva exclusively, as 
 well before the anarchy in inscriptions of about the 92nd 
 Olympiad (b.c. 412)*% as subsequently to it in a law preserved 
 in Demosthenes, which was doubtless passed in earlier times'*^ 
 in an inscription of Olymp. 98, 4 (b.c. 385), and in a passage 
 of ^schines referring to Olymp. 104, 4 (b.c. 361)*\ In like 
 manner each temple had its own treasurers, who, together 
 with the chief managers (eVtcrTaTal), and sacrificers {UpoTrocol), 
 administered the money which belonged to it*^. 
 
 But about the 90th Olympiad (b.c. 420), these treasurers 
 of the different temples, with the exception of the treasurers of 
 Minerva, were united into one board under the name of the 
 treasurers of the gods {ra/jLiaL tojv 6ecov), the nomination of 
 whom took place upon the same principles as that of the 
 treasurers of Minerva, and they also kept their treasures upon 
 the Acropolis (eV TroXei), and even in the opisthodomus''^ so that 
 from this time all the sacred money was preserved in the Acro- 
 polis. Whenever therefore after this period, the treasurers of the 
 sacred money in the Acropolis are mentioned (as for example in 
 
 ^^ Whereas the other gods only 
 received a fiftieth of certain things. 
 Concerning these tithes see book iii. 
 c. 6, 12, 14. 
 
 '**' See book iii. c. 20. 
 
 ^^ viii. 51, raixias tov lepov^ 
 
 *^ The superscription of the Choiseul j *^ Inscript. 76j § 6. 
 marble (n. 147). Of the same date 
 
 are Boeckh, Inscript. 139 and 141. 
 
 ^^ Ap. Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1075, 
 2. 
 
 ** Boeckh, Inscript. 151, and ^schin. 
 c. Timarch. p. 127. 
 
 *^ Inscript. 7C, v^ 7-
 
 162 
 
 TREASURER OF THE GODDESS. 
 
 [bk. U, 
 
 Andocides)*^ it cannot be determined without a farther specifica- 
 tion, which of these two offices is meant. As, moreover, according 
 to their original institution, the treasurers of the goddess and 
 the treasurers of the gods were entirely different authorities, 
 so they afterwards remained separate: a fact which the mention 
 in Demosthenes of the treasurers of the goddess as an indepen- 
 dent office, and their opposition to the treasurers of the gods, 
 distinctly prove*^ However, they once occur unequivocally 
 united as one office, viz. in Olymp. 95f (b.c. 397)'% in which 
 instance the treasurers of the goddess and of the other gods 
 [rafjLLac rcov Upcov ')(^pr}fidT(i)V rrjs *A6r]vd<; Kal rcbv aXkmv Oeoyv) 
 were altogether only ten, instead of which the treasurers of 
 Minerva alone were originally ten, and consequently the 
 treasurers of the other gods created after their example were 
 the same in number. In their collective capacity they trans- 
 ferred the treasures of Minerva as well as of other gods; for 
 example, of Jupiter Polieus, and of Diana of Brauron. This 
 union was not, however, of long duration; there can be no 
 doubt that about the 9Sth Olympiad (b.c. 388), the treasurers 
 of the goddess again existed independently, and were ten in 
 number^''. At that time, therefore, the treasurers of the gods 
 must have been again separate from them. 
 
 Concerning the treasurers of the goddess, Harpocration and 
 Pollux furnish us with more exact accounts, derived from Aris- 
 totle^\ Of these officers, then, we learn that there were ten 
 chosen by lot from among the pentacosiomedimni ; after this 
 class was abolished, a fixed valuation was probably established 
 
 '*7 De Myst. p. 65, where the word 
 Trpov^dWovTo does not suit the office 
 of treasurer, the candidates for which 
 were not proposed, but is inaccurately- 
 put in conjunction with it. So that 
 the passage must be understood as if 
 it stood in this manner : e'lcop fxe Xaxelv 
 Ta/iiav. 
 
 « Cont. Timocrat. p. 743, 1. Ol 
 rafiiai, 6(^' cov 6 'OmcrOodofios ive- 
 npfjadrj, Koi ol tcop ttjs deov, kol ol tSuv 
 aWfjiv Oeav. The words of the decree 
 
 in Andoc. de Myst. p. 36, tovs rafiias 
 TTJs Oeov KOL Tcov oXXcdv Bea>v, are an in- 
 accurate combination of two different 
 offices. 
 
 ^^ See Boeckh, Inscript. 150. 
 
 ^^ As is proved by Inscript. 151 
 (Superscription), where the vacant 
 space requires this number of names. 
 
 ^^ Harpocr. in v. rafiiai, Photius, 
 Suidas, Philemon Lex. Technol. (edited 
 by Burney), and Lex. Seg. p. 306; 
 Poll. viii. 97.
 
 CH. v.] AND OF THE OTHER GODS. 163 
 
 for them in some other manner". They received and transferred 
 the treasures^ monies, and valuables, particularly the statue of 
 Minerva, the statues of Victory, and all the other decorations, 
 in the presence of the senate^^, like the apodectse; they received 
 for the purpose of custody the fines which accrued to the god- 
 dess; and they had, as is proved from Demosthenes, the power 
 of cancelling a judicial sentence relating to them. Under their 
 superintendence was placed all the precious furniture of the 
 temple of Minerva upon the Acropolis, including, as we learn 
 from the oration of Demosthenes against Timocrates", the tro- 
 phies of the state {to, dpLo-reta rrjs TroXew?), Xerxes' silver- 
 footed stool, the golden sabre of Mardonius, and an immense 
 collection of valuable articles in the Parthenon and its interior 
 cell, the catalogues of which are still extant in several inscrip- 
 tions. The office was annual; at the expiration of each year 
 the predecessors transferred to their successors all that had 
 been originally delivered to them, and whatever had accrued 
 since their instalment in the office; the duties of the treasurers 
 of the other gods were similar, as their office was arranged on 
 the very same principles as the former. 
 
 Everything that has been hitherto mentioned as being under 
 the care of the two boards of treasurers was sacred property 
 (lepd). But to whom belonged the superintendence of the 
 money preserved in the treasury upon the Acropolis, which was 
 not considered as sacred property {oaca y^prjixara) ? According 
 to a very probable account given in Suidas^% the public monies 
 were kept by treasurers chosen by lot, who had the care of the 
 statue of Minerva, alluding manifestly to the treasurers of the 
 goddess. For all money which was brought into the treasury 
 by virtue of a decree of the people (whither it was transmitted 
 by the apodectee), was looked upon as dedicated to Minerva'% 
 although it could not have been considered as her immediate 
 property, and it was consequently placed under the care of the 
 
 *^ See book iv. c. 5. 
 
 °^ Upon this subject compare In- 
 script. 76j $ 7j in reference to the trea- 
 surers of the gods. 
 
 "' P. 741. Cf. Sigon. R. A. iv. 3. 
 
 '^ In V. Tafiiai in the first article. 
 
 5® According to Inscript. 76, § 2, 
 erreibfj rfj ^Adrjvaia to. rptcr;^iXia Takaura 
 du^vfiveyKTUi es noXitff a €yf/rj(f)iaTO. 
 
 M 2
 
 %6i TREASURERS OF THE GODDESS AND GODS. [bK. II. 
 
 treasurers of the goddess ; the latter repaid it upon the authority 
 of a decree of the people; thus, according to the Choiseul 
 inscription, considerable sums were paid by them to the helle- 
 notamiee and others, partly out of the treasures of Minerva 
 Polias and of the goddess of Victory, and partly perhaps from 
 the public treasure. The treasurers of the goddess were there- 
 fore not merely treasurers of a temple in the more limited sense, 
 but guardians also of the public treasure, and in this respect 
 theirs was no unimportant office: occasionally, also, they are 
 called treasurers simply {ra/jLiaiy^. Thus Androtion is called 
 treasurer, without any addition^^, although he could have held 
 no other office than that of treasurer of the goddess, for he had 
 •under his care the golden crowns, sacred offerings, and orna- 
 ments for processions belonging to Minerva in particular, and 
 other things preserved in the temple of that goddess, which he 
 obtained permission from the people to recast and alter. The 
 idea that Androtion must have been elected by the cheirotonia 
 of the people, as would be inferred from the account of Petit'% 
 is only founded upon a mistake of Ulpian, which ought not to 
 mislead any reader. It is scarcely necessary to remark, that 
 the treasurers were bound to leave the money unemployed, and 
 that it was a dishonest gain if they lent it out for their own 
 profit; a fraud which, according to Ulpian, upon the oration 
 against Timocrates, was once actually committed^". 
 
 Chapter VL 
 
 TTie Manager of the Public Revenue, or Treasurer of the Admi- 
 nistration. Subordinate Collectors. 
 
 Wholly different from these offices was the treasurer or 
 manager of the public revenue {Ta/xLa^ or iTnjjLeXTjrr]^ r?}? Koivrj<: 
 TTpoaoBov), the most important of all offices of finance, which 
 was filled not by lot but by the cheirotonia of the people. 
 
 *7 Cf. Ilarpocr. Suid. &c. 
 
 ^« Demostli. c. Androt. p. 615, 17- 
 
 ^9 Leg. Att. iii. 2, 33. 
 
 ^^ From this Demosthenes nepl na- 
 panpea-^eias, p. 435, 8, must probably 
 be explained.
 
 CH. VI.J MANAGER OF THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 165 
 
 Aristides held this situation, to which he was elected by chei- 
 rotonia®'; Lj^sias is expressly called in the decree, by which 
 honours were conferred upon him after his death^^, treasurer of 
 the public revenue {rafxlas T7]<i Kocvrj<i vrpoaoBov), and immedi- 
 diately afterwards it is observed that he was chosen by the 
 people. Also in the Lives of the Ten Orators^^ a law is men- 
 tioned, in which this treasurer is said to have been elected by 
 cheirotonia for the charge of the public money (o x^Lporoi^rjOel^ 
 eVt ra hrjfjLoaLa ')(pi]fjLaTa); and the remark made by Ulpian 
 that it was necessary that the treasurer should be elected by 
 cheirotonia, is only true of this ofl&cer. This office, moreover, 
 was not annual, like those of the treasurers upon the Acropolis, 
 but was held for four years, that is to say, for a penteteris : it is 
 expressly related of Lycurgus, that he filled that office for three 
 penteterids^*; and Diodorus says that he administered the pub- 
 lic revenues for twelve years". In early times the same indi- 
 vidual could be re-elected more than once, as the example of 
 Aristides proves; but after the first penteteris of Lycurgus, the 
 jealousy of the citizens was sufficiently strong to procure the 
 enactment of a law, by which all persons were from that time 
 prohibited from holding this situation for more than fi v^e years 
 {fjLTj irkelu) irevre ircov BciTretv rov ')(^eip0T0V7]6evTa iirl ra B7]fx6ata 
 '^prjfiara): on which account Lycurgus, in the two following 
 periods, transacted the business under the names of other per- 
 sons^^ The mention of five years might lead one to suppose 
 that the office was held for that period; but the expression 
 must be considered as inexact, and the word used in the law 
 was doubtless penteteris, and not five years; a penteteris ac- 
 cording to the ancient usage was never more than four years, 
 although the idiom subsequently changed, as may be seen from 
 the language of some later writers". Many of the periods 
 
 ^' Plutarch. Aristid. 4, where he is 
 called €7nixeKr)TT]s t5>v kolvwv Trpoaodcov. 
 
 ^'^ Decree iii. at the end of the Lives 
 of the Ten Orators. 
 
 •'^ In Lycurg. Petit (ut sup.) con- 
 fuses this whole subject most igno- 
 rantly. lie does not deserve refutation. 
 
 ^^ Lives of the Ten Orators (from 
 the third Decree), and thence Photius. 
 
 ^^ Diod. xvi. 88, ficoSfica err] tcis 
 rrpoaodovs rrjs noXecos 8ioiKrj(ras. 
 
 ^^ Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 251, vol. vi. of 
 the Tubingen Phitarcli. 
 
 ^^ Arrian. Epict. iii. 25. Cyrill.
 
 166 
 
 MANAGER OF THE PUBLIC REVENUE, OR [bK. U 
 
 employed in matters of finance were undoubtedly of four years, 
 particularly the assessment of the tributes, which is distinctly 
 stated to have taken place every penteteris (every four years) : 
 thence arose the duration of the office in question. There were 
 also other offices at Athens which were held for four years, 
 being regulated by the great Panathensea; but none, as far as I am 
 aware, for five years. The periodical beginning of the office of 
 treasurer probably fell in the year of the great Panathensea, in 
 the third year of each Olympiad, about the commencement of 
 the winter^®. 
 
 However considerable the situation of chief manager of the 
 public revenue may have been, his power in administering the 
 finances was by no means unhmited, but like every other officer 
 he was subject to the restraint of legal checks and of the will of 
 the people; nor was this office by any means the exclusive 
 source from which all financial measures proceeded; for every 
 person who had the right of speaking in the assembly and the 
 senate, every orator and demagogue, was at liberty to originate 
 any measure^®; and perhaps there existed in early times sepa- 
 rate officers, whose duty it was to procure the necessary reve- 
 nues, and to attend solely to that point. The author of the 
 Rhetorical Lexicon'^" declares, that the duties of the poristse 
 [TTopLaTal) were of this nature, and Antiphon classes them 
 with the poletae and the practores^^ It is upon the whole 
 
 Hierosol. Catech. xii. 8, call a period 
 of four years TerpaeTia. Concerning 
 the question whether in the treasurer- 
 ship of Lycurgus the periods were of 
 four or five years, see also book ii. 
 c. 19. 
 
 ^^ See Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 
 157. 
 
 ^® I remark incidentally that Gillies 
 (Observations upon the History, Cus- 
 to»is, and Character of the Greeks, p. 
 136 of the German translation,) sup- 
 poses that the demagogues, Eucrates 
 the wool-merchant, Lysicles the sheep- 
 dealer, Ilyperbolus the lamp-m;iker, 
 and Cleon tlie leather-seller, were trea- 
 
 sirrers, which appears to be a false in- 
 ference from Aristoph. Eq. 101 sqq. 
 since whatever power they possessed, 
 even were it extended to financial 
 matters, was entirely derived from 
 their character as demagogues. 
 
 '" Lex. Seg. 294, 19. nopiarai- 
 nopiarai elaiv (ipxv "'''■^ ^A6r]VT]mv, tJtls 
 TTopovs i^rjTei' aizo tovtov yap Kcti npo' 
 o-TjyopevOrjaav. 
 
 '' Uepl Tov xopcvToVf p. 791, extr. 
 Demosthenes (Philip, i.p. 49, 17) joins 
 Tcbu )(pT]fxa.Ta)v rapiai Koi Tropiaraly but 
 he uses the word in such a manner 
 that it cannot be inferred that it was 
 a public office in his time.
 
 CH. VI.] TREASURER OF THE ADMINISTRATION. 16/ 
 
 extremely difficult to define the extent of the duties and authority 
 of the manager of the public revenue. He was not Hke the 
 apodectee^ an officer who only received money, which they 
 immediately paid over, nor, like the treasurers upon the Acro- 
 polis, was he merely a guardian of monies, which in the regular 
 course of things were never re-issued. The example of Lycur- 
 gus proves, that all the money which was received and dis- 
 bursed passed through his hands; consequently, he was the 
 general receiver and superintendent of the offices of payment, 
 or general paymaster, who received all the money paid to the 
 apodectae and appointed for fresh disbursements, and supplied 
 the separate offices with the requisite sums; with the exception 
 of the property-taxes, which were doubtless paid directly into 
 the war-office, as war-supplies. The tributes originally formed 
 an exception, since as long as they were independent of the 
 finances of Athens, they remained under the management of 
 the hellenotamiee, a separation which was perhaps retained 
 until the abolition of those officers. 
 
 The manager of the revenue defrayed all expenses that were 
 necessary for the administration {Bt,0LK7]a-i<i)', to which all the 
 regular expenses in time of peace belonged. In the first place, 
 the duties {reXrj) were assigned to this department, together 
 with certain other contributions^^ The keeping and manage- 
 ment of these monies therefore unquestionably devolved upon 
 this officer. As the payment of the judges^ salaries evidently 
 belongs to the administration, the justice-fees, although there 
 existed a particular office for them, must likewise have been 
 under his direction; neither can there be any doubt that he 
 exercised a general superintendence over the collection of all 
 the revenues; for it could only have been by virtue of this 
 authority that Lycurgus was able to prevent the farmer of the 
 duties from requiring protection-money of Xenocrates'% and 
 that Aristides was enabled to point out the frauds and embez- 
 zlements of the pubhc money^*; and hence alone it can be 
 explained how Lycurgus was able to increase every branch of 
 
 7^ Demosth. c. Timocr. p. 731, 4. '^ Vit. Dec. Orat. in Lycurg. 
 
 ^* Plutarcli. Aristid. ut sup.
 
 168 MANAGER OF THE PUBLIC REVENUE, OR [bK. II. 
 
 the revenue, to purchase many valuable ornaments for the pub- 
 lic use, and to lay by a surplus sufficient for the construction of 
 great buildings and fleets^^ In short, the manager of the public 
 revenue had alone of all the public officers, the whole superin- 
 tendence of the revenue and expenditure, and was therefore in 
 a situation to give the surest judgment as to the possibility of 
 increasing the former and of diminishing the latter, and to pro- 
 pose beneficial measures to the senate and to the people ; he 
 was under other circumstances what the minister of finance is 
 in modern states. Valesius^® is probably correct in referring to 
 this treasurer a passage in Aristophanes, in which it is said that 
 the treasurer had the seal of the people; although it is possible 
 that it might have likewise been entrusted to the treasurers 
 upon the Acropolis, for the purpose of sealing the room in 
 which the treasure was kept"^ 
 
 The manager of the public revenue, being an officer who 
 disbursed money, bore the name of treasurer of the administra- 
 tion (rayLt/a? rr)? hLOiKr](Te(o^, or 6 eVt rr)? BLOLKr}(Teco<;), which 
 latter office is identical with the first. ^Eschines'^ says, that 
 Aphobetus, who was appointed for the administration (eVt ttjv 
 KOLvr]v SioUrjcrcv), also managed the public revenues justly and 
 honourably {koXco^ kuI hiKaiws rcov v/juerepcov Trpoaohcov Ittl- 
 fi6\7]6€L^): Lycurgus, when he filled the situation of manager 
 of the revenue, also superintended the administration {BioUrjais:), 
 as we learn from the authors of the Lives of the Ten Orators 
 and of the Epistles of Demosthenes^^ and is distinctly proved 
 by the fact that he annually paid out and accounted for the 
 whole revenue. Pollux^*' also sufficiently proves the identity of 
 these two offices, when he calls the person at the head of the 
 administration (6 iirl ttJs- Stot/c^Jo-eajs-), an officer for the revenue 
 and expenditure (eVl rcov Trpoacovrcov koI avakiaKOfjievoyv), 
 elected, not chosen by lot. In this capacity he must have 
 
 "''" Lives of the Ten Orators, and the 
 third decree preserved there. 
 
 '^ Ad Harpocrat. in v. u7ro6e/crat. 
 The passage of Aristophanes is Eq. 
 943, where the Schohast incorrectly 
 interprets it as if it was only the ad- 
 
 ministration of the prytaneia. 
 '' See Inscript. 76, ^S 6. 
 '^ Ilfpi TrapanpeaS^ p. 315. 
 '" Epist. iii. 
 **" viii. 113.
 
 CH. VlJ TREASURER OF THE ADMINISTRATION. 
 
 169 
 
 issued all payments for police, building, provision of ornaments 
 used in processions, public sacrifices, and the celebration of 
 festivals, the latter belonging to the sacred administration [Upa 
 ScoLK7j(ri<;)^\ in opposition to the civil {ocrta). Thus Lycurgus, 
 by virtue of this office, superintended the building of the wharfs, 
 of the gymnasia, palaestras, theatres, arsenal, &c., and the sup- 
 ply of articles for sacred uses^% as well as of the money required 
 for the provision of ships, arms, and artillery, which was ap- 
 pointed to be made in times of peace, a duty also performed by 
 Lycurgus; together with all salaries payable in time, of peace, and 
 the other expenses of the domestic administration. Particular 
 funds were also created for single parts of the administration, 
 which the treasurer of the public revenue provided with money. 
 The theoricon and the war-office were however undoubtedly 
 independent of his authority, and into one of these two funds he 
 paid all the surplus money which he received, as will be pre- 
 sently shown, after which he ceased to have any farther charge 
 of it; for a considerable time, indeed, a great part of the admi- 
 nistration itself was under the care of the treasurers of the 
 theoricon, several offices having been consolidated in them. 
 
 Two statements, from which it might seem that the manager 
 of the public revenue was also treasurer of the theoricon, admit of 
 a satisfactory explanation. Lycurgus obtained the condemna- 
 tion of Diphilus, who had committed some offence connected 
 with the mines, which this person held in lease of the state, and 
 distributed the confiscated property among the people, after the 
 manner of the theorica^\ This case, however, manifestly 
 proves nothing, as it was an extraordinary measure, and not in 
 the usual course of business. " When Demades had under him 
 the revenues of the state,^^ says Plutarch^*, "the Athenians 
 being eager to dispatch some vessels to the assistance of those 
 who had revolted from Alexander, called upon him to supply 
 them with money; from which project he succeeded in dissuad- 
 
 *^ Xenoph. Hellen. vi. 1,2; cf. De- 
 mosth. c. Timocrat. p. 7^0, 24 ; p. 
 
 731, 
 
 ^^ Lives of the Ten Orators. 
 ^'' Ibid. 
 
 ^^ Prsec. Reip. Ger. 25, ore ras npo- 
 (Todovs elx^v v(f)' iavTfo tt^s noXecos. 
 The date of the event is 01}nnp. 112, 
 2 (b.c. 331). See Diod. xx. 62, and 
 Wesseling's note.
 
 170 SUBORDINATE COLLECTORS OF [bK. II. 
 
 ing the people by answering to them, ' Money you certainly are 
 provided with, for I have so arranged it that each citizen should 
 receive half a mina at the Choeis; but if you prefer applying 
 it to this purpose, make what use you please of your own pro- 
 perty/ " From the writer's expression it might at first sight 
 be thought that Demades was manager of the public revenue: 
 but as Demades appears solely in the capacity of a director of 
 the theorica, who at the festivals and games distributed money 
 among the citizens ; and as Plutarch's words that " he had the 
 revenues of the state under Mm,'' do not necessarily refer to a 
 treasurer of the administration, we should not, in my opinion, 
 be justified in assuming that he filled the latter office, to which 
 so thoughtless and extravagant a man must appear but ill 
 adapted. For a manager of the theorica he was much better 
 fitted; since the more careless and immoral a person in that 
 situation was, the more could be expected from his administra- 
 tion of the office. Demades had contrived that the coffers of 
 the theorica should be well filled; in time of war, however, 
 these funds were always claimed by the well-disposed for military 
 preparations; and the contest which was carried on at Athens, 
 as to whether the money of the theorica was or was not to be 
 applied to the uses of war, has become notorious. If this 
 latter fact is taken in connexion with the above narration, it will 
 evidently appear that Demades had not the entire administration 
 of the public revenue, but only of the money of the theorica. 
 
 For the superintendence of works of architecture, such as 
 the building of walls, streets, wharfs, and ships, and for the pro- 
 vision of sacrifices, separate authorities were appointed {reixo- 
 TTOtol, oBoTTOiol^ iirLfieXrjTal to)V vecoptcov, rptrjp otto col, lepoiroLol 
 Kar iviavTov and iTTL/jbrivioi, &c.), some of whom remained in 
 office for a whole year, while others acted only as special com- 
 missioners for a shorter period^'. All these officers had their 
 respective paymasters dependent upon the several treasurers of 
 the administration. It is proved by inscriptions^^ that money 
 was paid into the hands of the managers of the sacrifices as well 
 as to the athlothetcc; and although it appears that money was 
 
 .Esch. c. Ctesiph. p. 425. «« See Inscript. 144 and 147-
 
 CH. VI.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 171 
 
 sometimes paid into their hands by the treasurers of the god- 
 dess, these payments must be considered wholly as contribu- 
 tions, since according to the regular course their money ought 
 to have been derived from the funds of the administration^^ 
 The treasurer of the ship-builders [rajjiias rayv rpLrjpoTroicov) is 
 particularly mentioned^% as well as the treasurers of the builders 
 of the walls {rafMiai rcov retp^oTrotwv), and it is expressly stated 
 that the latter received their money from the funds of the 
 administration^^; Demosthenes mentions among other duties of 
 the administration the payment for the wages of the dicasts, of 
 the assembly, of the senate, and of the cavalry^*': for these par- 
 ticular payments separate boards must necessarily have been 
 appointed under the treasurer of the administration; yet we 
 find that in the Peloponnesian war, the hellenotamiee disbursed 
 money out of the treasury for the cavalry '^ The thesmothetee 
 paid the wages of the assembly^^ out of the monies of the admi- 
 nistration, and they probably had also their own paymasters for 
 that purpose. Lastly, since the sacred triremes received pay 
 even in time of peace (the Paralos certainly, and probably 
 also the Salaminia and the Ammonis), it is natural to suppose 
 that their treasurers were in a great measure under the super- 
 intendence of the treasurer of the administration. The treasurer 
 of the Paralos was an officer of distinction, and he was appointed 
 by cheirotonia, as much money passed through his hands in 
 addition to that which was paid for the uses of the vessel: 
 the others were elected in the same manner®^: these trea- 
 surers of the sacred triremes (respecting v/hom Harpocration 
 and Pollux, and other grammarians have derived their know- 
 ledge from Aristotle) supplied the expenses of the trierarch^^ 
 
 ^7 Because they were for the lepa 
 SioiKr^o-is-, Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 
 730, 24 ; p. 731, 1. 
 
 88 Demosth. c. Androt. p. 598. 
 
 8^ 'Ek TTJs 8loikt}(T€cos. See jEsch. c. 
 Ctesiph. p. 425, p. 426, p. 415, p. 422. 
 
 »° C. Timocrat. p. 731, 1—5, and 21, 
 22. 
 
 ^^ See the Choiseul Inscription (n. 
 147). 
 
 ^^ See book ii. c. 14. 
 
 ^2 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 570, 3, 13, 
 15, and more particularly 1, 24, and 
 Ulpian's note. 
 
 ^* This is the way in which Pollux 
 (viii. 116) should be understood, rafiias 
 €Kakovv Tovs Tois Upais Tpirjpecri Xei- 
 Tovpyovvras, aXXovs de rptTjpdp^ovs. 
 The state was properly the trierarch 
 of the sucred trii-emes; but it was ne-
 
 I>j2 SUBORDINATE COLLECTORS OF [bK. II. 
 
 Smaller payments of a domestic nature were probably made at 
 once by the treasurer of the administration, without the ap- 
 pointment of a particular board. Thus the charge for engraving 
 the decrees was assigned to him''. This duty on one occasion 
 fell upon the treasurer of the people {raiLia^ rov hrjfiov), by 
 which the same office is meant, and it is particularly directed 
 that the payments should be made out of the money set apart 
 for the expenses of the decrees {ra e? ra '>\n)<l)l(j^iaTa avaXiaKo- 
 fjLeva Tw Byjfi<p). This belongs to Olymp. 125, 2 (b.c. 279)'^ 
 In two other decrees there occurs a remarkable variation. In 
 the one, which is of later date than Olymp. 119, 1 (b.c. 304), it 
 is ordered that the cost of engraving should be defrayed by the 
 treasurers of the administration {ol eirl rfj BcocKrjaeLy', in the 
 other, which is of the age of Demosthenes, it is assigned to the 
 treasurers {ra/jLcac), without any further specification'^ The 
 latter are doubtless the same as those who in the first decree are 
 
 cessaiythat they should have trierarchs j Diog. Laert. vii. in the Life of Zeno, 
 who represented the state. The reading the date of which is unknown, but 
 of Juno-eiTuanu's manuscript, rj for 8e, which is later than the 130th OIjtu- 
 is probably correct. Hai-pocration, and piad (260 b.c.) where he is distinctly 
 from him Suidas, say, eiVt Se rives kqi called 6 eVi ttjs dioiKrjo-ecos. 
 Tcov TpiT]p(ov rafxiai, (us 6 avros (piXo- \ ^^ See the third Decree after the 
 (ro<j)6s (pr](Tiv,viz. Aristotle, a passage • Lives of the Ten Orators, 
 which refers to the sacred trii-emes ! ^^ Decret. ap. Chandl. Inscript. ii. 
 alone, as is proved by Photivis in v. ^ 12, ad fin. Mepiaai, the expression 
 rajxlai, eiVi he kol aXKoi Tafiiai apxovres here used, refers to the items of the 
 XeipnTov7]To\ enl ras lepas Kal brjuoaias different heads of the expenditure, as 
 rpiTjpeis, 6 p.ev en\ ttjv irapoKov, 6 be in the Decree in Diog. Laert. and the 
 i-nX Tov "Apificovos. Arjfxoaiai is here ' Decree of the Tyrian merchants at 
 put in opposition to those furnished at ' Delos, in Boeckh, Corp. Inscript. No. 
 the expense of the trierarchs. Thefol- 2271, ad fin. ; also in the Salaminian 
 lowing observation from the Maricas Decree, ibid. No. 108, where there is 
 of Eupolis appears to refer to trea- the following sentence : p-eplaai 8e tov 
 surers of all the trierarchs, and will be rap-iav ^iXoKXiiv Ileipaiea eK tcov els to. 
 considered in a subsequent part of this x-aTo. -^r^fpLa-paTa dvaXio-Kopevcov rw 
 work, although a definitive decision is brjpa. 
 
 not possible, as is remarked in bookiv. ' ®^ Decree for Straton, king of Sidon, 
 c. 1 1. The treasurer of the Ammonis is in the Marm. Oxon. xxiv. ed. Chandl. 
 mentioned by both Suidas and Photius line 16. I omit the Decree which 
 in V. rapiai. The state moreover paid Chishull lias given from Ainswortli in 
 the money directly into the hands of ' Ant. Asiat. p. 164, because the trea- 
 the trierarchs, as is shown elsewhere. surer of the city is inserted in it by 
 ^* As for iiibtance in the Decree in conjecture.
 
 CH. VI.] THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 173 
 
 called ol eirl rfj htoiKrjaeL ; for it is manifest that these were the 
 only treasurers who could have paid the money : but it is 
 remarkable that several treasurers of the administration are here 
 mentioned, as nothing is stated in any other place of there having 
 been more than one. At all events this increase of the number 
 can only have been temporary : from the nature of the pro- 
 ceedings we should expect that frequent alterations would take 
 place in the administration of finance, and both before and after 
 these decrees we find only one treasurer of the administration 
 mentioned. 
 
 The statement made above upon the authority of Pollux®% 
 that a separate ofiice was created for paying the wages of the 
 dicasts, which was dependent upon the treasurers of the 
 administration, will be more clearly illustrated by the consi- 
 deration of the colacretse, respecting whom all that occurs in 
 the ancient writers has been collected by Ruhnken'*"^, without 
 any light having been thrown upon the nature of their pro- 
 blematical office. The singular name by which they are desio-- 
 nated, is of itself sufficient to prove that they had their origin 
 in very remote times; they were called KwiXaKperai, from 
 collecting certain parts of the victims (properly KCDXayperat)^'^^, 
 an expression which shows that they must have been the 
 superintendents of the provisions at certain pubUc feasts ; and 
 this supposition agrees with well-estabhshed facts, which we 
 shall mention presently. They also took charge of the gifts, 
 which the kings in the most ancient times, and afterwards the 
 archons and prytanes in their capacity of judges, received for 
 the administration of justice, and they had the management of 
 everything connected with financial matters, such at least as at 
 that time could have been in existence. It is possible that 
 Pyrander who is said by the ancients to have been treasurer at 
 so remote a period as that of the Eleusinian war, was only a 
 colacretes of the king ; and as we find in use at Cyzicus a verb 
 
 ^^ Ym.lldjwhere 6 €7rl TTJs dioLKTja-ccos | '°^ As Tinifeus (p. 171) and Photius 
 is mentioned in connexion with the write according to the derivation. See 
 pay of the dicasts. Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 693, and thence 
 
 '"" Ad Tim. Plat. Lex. p. 171. ; Suidas in his second article.
 
 174 
 
 SUBORDINATE COLLECTORS OF 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 which was derived from the office of colacretse, it is evident 
 that they came with the ancient colony of Neleus to Miletus, 
 and from thence to Cyzicus, like the Diana of Munychia, and 
 the names of the four ancient Athenian tribes. Solon left the 
 colacretse untouched, acting on a policy which he appears to 
 have followed in numerous instances ; Cleisthenes, always fond 
 of iimovation, established the apodectae in their stead'"^; the 
 colacretae were now no longer receivers of the taxes, but became 
 a subordinate department : but what was its nature ? According 
 to the Great Etymologist, they were treasurers of the money and 
 managers of the trierarchy. This could only have been the 
 case before the time of Cleisthenes, when indeed they might 
 have had all the liturgies of the citizens under their superin- 
 tendence, including the provision of the triremes ; as to the 
 later period in which we have more accurate information 
 respecting the trierarchy, this assertion is absurd, nor does there 
 anywhere occur the slightest confirmation of it ; neither could 
 they after the time of Cleisthenes have been treasurers upon 
 the Acropolis and guardians of the sacred money, although 
 Pollux^ °^ confounds them with the treasurers of the goddess. 
 All that we know for certain is, that they paid the wages of the 
 dicasts'", a fact which appears as well from passages in the 
 grammarians, as from the testimony of the poet Aristophanes'"^ 
 These stipends they probably distributed in person, as subor- 
 dinate officers to the treasurer of the administration. Aristo- 
 phanes the grammarian expressly asserts, as well as Hesychius, 
 that they had nothing to attend to except the payment of the 
 dicasts*°% a testimony which of all others is deserving of the 
 greatest credit. According to a statement in the Rhetorical 
 Lexicon'"^, they had authority over the fines in the courts of 
 justice; but this is evidently a mistake, the reason of which 
 
 '"^ Androtion ap. Ilarpocrat. in v. 
 
 UTTobeKTai. 
 
 ^"3 viii. 97. 
 
 '"* Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. G93 and 
 723; Av. 1540; Photius and Timreus 
 ut sup. Lex. Sog. p. 275. Hesychius 
 and Suidas in v. KUiXuKpcTm, the second 
 
 article of the latter grammarian being 
 taken from the Scholiast of Aristo- 
 phanes. 
 
 '"^ In the passages just quoted. 
 
 ^"^ Aristoph. Granimat. ap. Schol. 
 Aristoph. Av. 1540 ; Ilesych. ut sup. 
 
 '*^7 Lex. Seg. p. 190, 50.
 
 CH. VI.] THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 175 
 
 however is that the prytaneia and the other justice-fees, which 
 the grammarian might call fines, were set apart for paying the 
 dicasts, and consequently either directly or indirectly were 
 delivered over to the colacretee. The Scholiast to Aristo- 
 phanes'"^ again enumerates the provision of the pubhc enter- 
 tainments in the prytaneum as one of their duties, a circumstance 
 of so little importance that Aristophanes the grammarian pro- 
 bably did not think proper to mention it: and indeed we are 
 compelled to suppose that they performed this or some analo- 
 gous duty; for as their office originated before the time of 
 Cleisthenes, and the wages of the dicasts were first introduced 
 by Pericles, they must between these two periods have per- 
 formed some duty; and this was doubtless the management of 
 the entertainments in the prytaneum, a relic of their more 
 ancient office. The single fact that the justice-fees were called 
 prytaneia proves that they were once paid to the prytanes, as 
 judges in the prytaneum; which money may have been allotted 
 to defraying the expenses of their meals (what relation the 
 prytanes bore to the archons with regard to the judicial 
 authority, the latter being also judges, is foreign to the present 
 question) : and when the payment of the dicasts was afterwards 
 introduced, it seemed for this reason the obvious and natural 
 course to assign to them this latter duty. Thus we find a 
 perfect agreement between two duties which at first sight 
 appeared of a very different nature; and it cannot well be 
 doubted that they continued from this time forth to perform 
 both together. 
 
 We must now examine what is adduced by the Scholiast to 
 the Birds of Aristophanes, in order to confute the assertion of 
 Aristophanes the grammarian, which I have generally followed 
 in the above discussion. Androtion the antiquary had written, 
 that according to some law the colacretse were bound to furnish 
 the Pythian theori with money for their voyage and other 
 expenses out of the vavKkrjpiKd ; from this circumstance the 
 colacretee have been considered the same with the treasurers of 
 Minerva, and the grammarians have derived their statement from 
 
 ^"8 Av. 1540.
 
 176 
 
 SUBORDINATE COLLECTORS OF REVENUE. [bK. II. 
 
 this authority that the funds for the festivals or for the gods'"' 
 were under their regulations. We shall in vain attempt to dis- 
 cover what the vavKXrjptKawere: it is clear, however, to me that 
 the monies of the naucrarias (properly vavKpapcKa according to 
 the ancient form) are meant; but it also appears to me probable 
 that Androtion, who as well as Philochorus had in some things 
 an extensive, in others an imperfect, knowledge of the earliest 
 times of the Athenian state, spoke of the regulations anterior to 
 Cleisthenes in the passage in which he quoted this law. In 
 this manner Aristophanes the grammarian and Androtion can 
 be easily reconciled; and we need not consider that the cola- 
 cretse continued to be treasurers of the sacred monies after the 
 time of Cleisthenes, which would not accord with other ascer- 
 tained facts. 
 
 The Hellenot amice . 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 
 the Funds for War, and the Funds for the 
 Theorica. 
 
 A separate office existed during some time for the manage- 
 ment of the tributes, the hellenotamise or treasurers of the 
 Greeks; to these the administration of the monies at Delos, or 
 the eWrjvora/jLLa, belonged' '% when in consequence of the 
 treachery of Pausanias after the battle of Platsea (Olymp. 75, 2, 
 B.C. 479), Athens had obtained the command, and that treasury 
 had been created on the suggestion of Aristides. This situation 
 was at first exclusively held by Athenians : the duty attached 
 to it was to receive the tributes, and to deposit them in the 
 Delian treasury in the temple of Apollo, where the meetings of 
 the allies were heW\ There can be no doubt that they con- 
 tinued to be the guardians of these monies''^; their office was 
 
 '<"* Ap. Schol. Aristoph. A v. 1540 ; 
 Vesp. 623; Timaeus, Lex. Seg. and 
 Pliotius. 
 
 ''" Xenoph. de Vectig. 5, 5, unless 
 the right reading is (XXrjvoTafjLidas. 
 
 '" Thiicyd. i. 9G ; Nepos Aristid. 3 ; 
 Plutarch. Aristid. 24; Andocid. de 
 
 Pace, p. 107, which] oration was called 
 in question by the ancients, but is evi- 
 dently the production of Andocides. 
 Antiplion also (de caede Herod, p. 739), 
 mentions the office, without our de- 
 riving any information from him. 
 ''■' Schol. Thucyd. i. 9fi.
 
 CH. VII.] THE HELLEXOTAMI^. l77 
 
 retained when the funds were removed to Athens under the 
 pretence of greater security, a proceeding which Aristides 
 declared to be unjust, though expedient: but the whole injus- 
 tice of it became first manifest through the lavish expendi- 
 ture of Pericles'^'. After the Anarchy, no more traces of the 
 hellenotamiee occur; under the new administration they were 
 not re-established, the ascendancy of Athens and the tributary 
 condition of the allies having ceased: and although Athens was 
 again enabled to exact tributes from the dependent states, this 
 office was never again created for the management of them''"*. 
 For this reason the grammarians know scarcely anything of 
 these treasurers: Harpocration says, upon the authority of 
 Aristotle, that they were an office at Athens which had the 
 management of money; the Etymologist affirms that they were 
 the guardians of the common monies of Greece; Suidas"^ fur- 
 nishes nothing that is not known from other sources; Pollux''^ 
 asserts that they collected the tributes, and had under their 
 superintendence the constitutions of the tributary islands; 
 whereas the latter duty rather belonged to the episcopi, and the 
 former was wholly unnecessary, as the tributaries themselves 
 paid in the money during the spring at the time of the Diony- 
 sia"^, which were celebrated annually in the city; particular 
 persons for collecting them {eKXoyel^) were appointed only 
 upon extraordinary occasions, who were different from the 
 hellenotamiee; Hesychius is most correct in calling them the 
 treasurers of the tribute accruing to the Athenians"^. But the 
 best information concerning them is affi)rded by some inscrip- 
 
 ^'^ Plutarch. Aristid. 25; Pericl. 12; I ^'^ Aristoph. Acham. 504, and the 
 Nepos ut sup. Diod. xii. 38. I Scholiast ; ibid. 643. The date of the 
 
 ''•' The Hellenotamias, who accord- ' Acharneans is 01}Tiip. 88, 3 (b.c. 426). 
 ing to the Lives of the Ten Orators | That the great Dionysia took place 
 (in the Life of Lycurgus) was banished j annually has been showji by Corsini 
 in the Democracy after the thirty i and others against the unimportant 
 tyrants, had previously held this office, testimony of Scholiasts 
 
 ''' Vol. i. p. 715. 
 
 "^ viii. 14. Zonaras in v. 'eWtjvq- 
 Ta/xtat, where it should be written eV 
 A17X&), hardly desei-A^es to be men- j tirely pass over 
 tioned. 
 
 Ol Tov KOfii^o^evov (f)6pov TTupa 
 'hO-qvalois rafxiai. An incorrect article 
 in Lex. Seg. p. 188 {8ik. ovofx.) I en- 
 
 N
 
 IJQ THE HELLENOTAMI^. [bK. II. 
 
 tions of a date anterior to the archonship of Euclid. The form 
 of their nomination is unknown; it seems, however, pro- 
 bable that they were chosen by lot, like the treasurers of the 
 gods, out of the pentacosiomedimni. Barthelemy'^' says that 
 they were ten in number, one out of each tribe: not only have 
 I been unable to find any confirmation of this assertion, but I 
 am able distinctly to refute it. In the Choiseul inscription 
 (Olymp. 92, 3, B.C. 410), eleven hellenotamise are mentioned; 
 Callimachus of Hagnus, Phrasitelides of Icaria, Pericles of 
 Cholargus, Dionysius of Cydathenseum, Thrason of Butade, 
 Proxenus of Aphidna, Spudias of Phlyee, Aneetius of Sphettus, 
 Phalanthus of Alopecse, Eupolis of Aphidna, and Callias of 
 Euonymia, of whom Pericles and Ansetius were of the same 
 tribe Acamantis, and the two Aphidneeans of the tribe Leontis; 
 and still more, Pericles and Aneetius were both hellenotamise in 
 the same, viz., the sixth prytanea, and both the Aphidngeans in 
 like manner in the seventh. From this we are compelled to 
 suppose either that no regard w^as paid to the tribes (which was 
 not by any means necessary, as the office originaUy had no con- 
 cern with the home administration), or that several were chosen 
 out of each tribe. The former supposition appears to me the 
 most probable, and I conceive that their number was only ten, 
 and that they did not enter into their office at the beginning of 
 the year, but after the Panathensea and the first prytanea: if 
 this hypothesis is adopted, two of the persons who are men- 
 tioned, Callimachus and Phrasytelides, may be deducted from 
 the eleven, and we have only nine in the inscription, who were 
 colleagues in this office, the name of the tenth not having come 
 down to us. 
 
 Their duties are still more difficult to determine than their 
 number. When the funds were at Delos, they must have 
 acted at the same time both as apodectse and treasurers; 
 afterwards the apodectte appear to have received the tributes, 
 and the hellenotamise to have been merely the managers of the 
 fund thus collected''": when the tributes were commuted for a 
 
 "® M^m. de I'Acad. des Inscriptions, vol. xlviii. p. 341, 
 ^'■'^ Compare chap. 4.
 
 CH. Vlf.] THE FUNDS FOR WAR, ETC. 179 
 
 custom-duty, the hellenotamiae naturally remained as treasurers 
 for these payments. The payments for certain selected pur- 
 poses were assigned to their office; in the first place, that for 
 which the tributes were originally designed, namely, the ex- 
 penses of wars in the common cause, and federal solemnities; 
 but the Athenians afterwards considered the money as their 
 own property, and used it for buildings and works of art, 
 festivals, distributions, and theorica'*': the overplus was with- 
 out doubt laid by among the public treasure in the Acropolis, 
 which was chiefly formed from the tributes: but as soon as the 
 money had been sent to Athens, or even before it was actually 
 dispatched, and only its place of destination had been fixed, it 
 was no longer under the superintendence of these officers, but 
 of the treasurers of the goddess upon the Acropolis. We see 
 that money in their hands was assigned about the 90th Olym- 
 piad (420 B.C.) to the redemption of the public debts*^^; the 
 only example which we meet with of their having paid the 
 money out of their own fund. On the other hand in Olymp. 
 92, 3 (410 B.C.), money was appointed to be paid to them from 
 the public treasure for the provision of the cavalry, for diobelia, 
 and war expenses'*^: at this period the cavalry appears to have 
 been paid in time of peace by the hellenotamiae and not by the 
 treasurer of the administration : for the treasurer of war and the 
 managers of the theoricon were not introduced until after the 
 abolition of the hellenotamiee, who used to make all payments 
 of this description. There is nothing in the fact of money 
 being furnished to them from the public treasure, which ought 
 to surprise us: for if their own funds were exhausted, the 
 treasure would naturally be compelled to furnish whatever was 
 sufficient to enable them to pay that which belonged to their 
 department. In the same manner gold was lent to them out of 
 the treasury, to be paid to the athlothetse; but evidently from 
 the sacred money'"*. Hence the payments which they had to 
 make must have been considerable, and their duties cannot have 
 been unimportant. In order to execute these with the greater 
 
 '■'' riutarch. Aristid. 24 ; Pericl. 12. I ''" Inscript. 14?. 
 
 '^^ Inscript. 76, ^^ 3. I '"' Inscript. 144,3rd Prytan.lst item. 
 
 N Z
 
 180 
 
 THE FUNDS FOR WAR, 
 
 [bk. II, 
 
 facility they divided them among one another^"; and to assist 
 them they had as many as three superior archons as assessors 
 {7rdp€Bpoi,y^\ It must not with Barthelemy be thought singu- 
 lar that we only know of these officers from inscriptions, since 
 of the hellenotamiee themselves we have such imperfect ac- 
 counts. 
 
 As after the archonship of Euclid, no mention of hellenota- 
 miee occurs, so before that time we hear of no treasurers of war 
 or managers of the theorica; the former having performed all 
 the duties which subsequently belonged to the latter: and we 
 are thence justified in assuming, that by the changes in the 
 constitution made in the year of Euclid, two new offices, the 
 treasurer of war, and the manager of the theorica, were insti- 
 tuted. The name of treasurer of war {Ta/jLia<; arpaTKOTLKMv) 
 is only once made use of, and this in reference to one Callias, 
 who is stated by the author of the Lives of the Ten Orators ^*^ 
 to have held that office in the archonship of Chasrondas (Olymp. 
 110, 3, B.C. 338); probably it was only filled in time of war, and 
 discontinued when there was no armed force in motion. The 
 funds for meeting the expenses of war were, with the exception 
 of certain tributes, derived from two sources; which, however, 
 were both of a very uncertain nature. According to ancient 
 laws'" the surplus money of the administration was to be 
 applied in times of war to the use of the army [ra irepiovra 
 y^prjfiara rrj^ hioiKi-jcrews etvat arpaTLCdTLKa): but the people 
 had the madness to require that the surplus should always be 
 used for the distribution of the theorica; and the demagogue 
 Eubulus even succeeded in passing a law, that if any person 
 again proposed that the theorica should be applied to the uses 
 of war he should suffer death. This law, which crippled the 
 martial power of the Athenians, was frequently attacked by the 
 
 '■^* As is proved by Inscript. 147. 
 
 >*« Inscript. 147, Cth Trytan.; In- 
 script. 144, 3rd Prytan. 1st item, and 
 8th Prytan. 4th item. 
 
 ^^"^ In the Life of Lycuigus, accord- 
 ing to the correction of Sahnasius: 
 for he is geneially called KaKaios. 
 KAAAIOY and KAAAIOY only differ 
 
 by a line. 
 
 ^'^^ Orat. c. Neoer. p. 134G, 1347; 
 Liban. Argum.Olynth. i.; cf. Demosth. 
 Olynth. i. p. 14, 19, and Olyntli. iii. 
 (e.g. p. 31); Ilarpocr. in v. ^fcopi/ca, 
 and thence Siiidas and the Etymologist. 
 Cf. Ruhnk. Hist. Crit. Orat. p. 146, 
 viii. of Reiske's Orators.
 
 CH. VII.] 
 
 AND FOR THE THEORICA. 
 
 181 
 
 well disposed: Demosthenes complained that the Athenians, 
 though possessing large funds for war, squandered them away 
 upon festivals: ApoUodorus was condemned to a fine of fifteen 
 talents, for having proposed in Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353), that 
 the surplus money should be used for war, though for the time 
 he attained his object'^^: and although even Eubulus in later 
 times proposed that the theorica should be applied to the pur- 
 poses of war'^''; and although according to Philochorus^^*, all 
 the public money was at the instigation of Demosthenes, in 
 Olymp. 110, 2 (b.c. 339), applied to the military service, it was 
 frequently in the power of treacherous or inconsiderate dema- 
 gogues to deduct very large sums from the war funds by pro- 
 posing a donation of money to the people: of which unworthy 
 conduct Demades furnished a most striking instance. 
 
 Besides this, the extraordinary property-tax {€lo-<f)opa) was 
 set apart for the expenses of war'^^j but this being a tax which 
 was unwillingly paid, the coffers were generally empty. Many 
 higher as well as subordinate offices were requisite for the cus- 
 tody and disbursement of the war-funds. All those who bore 
 the name of generals (as we know for certain to have been the 
 case in the time of Demosthenes, and probably in earlier times 
 also) were not in fact commanders of all the troops, but only 
 generals of the infantry and cavalry of each separate army 
 (arparyyos 6 eVl tcov ottXcov or ottXctcov, and o iirl rcov lirireoyv): 
 of these, one in his capacity of general of the administration 
 {oTpaTrj<yo<; 6 iirl Trj9 BcocKfjo-ecos) performed part of the judicial 
 labours, together with other services: the duty of giving out the 
 pay of the troops also devolved upon him''% for which he must 
 have had a treasurer of his own. Among his proposals for the 
 equipment of the troops, Demosthenes^^* particularly recom- 
 
 ^29 Orat. c. Neser. p. 1346, 19. The 
 date is evident from book iv. cli. 13. 
 
 *^° Demosth. irepl napaTrpea^. p. 
 434, 24. 
 
 ^^^ Fragment, p. 76. 
 
 ^32 Demosth. e. Polycl. p. 1209, and 
 passim. 
 
 '3' Decret. ap. Demosth. de Corona, 
 p. 265, 11. 
 
 ^^* Orat. de Cherson. p. 101, 14. 
 From this the whole passage in the 
 fourth Philippic is borrowed (p. 137), 
 the spuriousness of which oration was 
 perceived by Valckenaer, in Ids notes 
 to his speech de Philipp. Maced. p. 
 251, and by Wolf Proleg. ad Le^t. 
 p. Ix.
 
 18^ 
 
 THE FUNDS FOR WAR, 
 
 [liK. II. 
 
 mends that treasurers and public slaves {8r]/x6aLot) should be 
 appointed for the custody of tlie war-funds, that the strictest 
 watch should be kept over their administration, and that these, 
 and not the generals, should give an account of the manner in 
 which the money had been employed. Many of the treasurers 
 of the generals, who are mentioned in different writers, appear 
 liowever to have been merely private paymasters, without being 
 in the service of the state; thus Philocrates was the treasurer 
 of Ergocles, and Antimachus of Timotheus, who managed ever}^- 
 thing for this general, and also kept a secretary for himself '^ 
 In the same manner the trierarchs had treasurers'^*. 
 
 By means of the theoricon- {to OecoptKov, ra OecopiKa, or 
 OecopiKCL j^^pTjfiaTa), the most pernicious institution in the age 
 of Pericles, there arose in a petty republic a lavishness of 
 expense, which was not proportionally less than that of the most 
 luxurious courts, and which swallowed up vast sums at the very 
 moment that the military operations were failing from want of 
 the proper supplies. Under the term Theorica are comprised 
 the monies which were distributed among the people, for 
 the celebration of festivals and games'", either to indemnify 
 them for the entrance-money to the theatre, or to enable them 
 to feast more plentifully: they were also in part expended upon 
 sacrifices"% with which a public entertainment was always com- 
 bined. From the nature and character of this expense it may 
 be expected that the surplus money of the administration was 
 set apart for it; in the early times, however, this was frequently 
 applied to replenishing or increasing the public treasure; 
 
 '3* Lysias c. Philocr. p. 829; De- 
 mosth. c. Timoth. p. 118G, 17; p. 1187, 
 10. 
 
 '^® Eupolis ap. Harpocrat. in v. 
 Tfi/xi'at. Comp. book iv. c. 11. Whe- 
 ther Antiphanes, tlie treasurer of the 
 ship's captain Philip (Demosth. c. Ti- 
 moth. p. 1188, 20; p. 1189, 2), was of 
 this description, or whether Philip was 
 only a private individual, I leave un- 
 decided. By the treasuier who gave 
 the crowu to the trieraich that was 
 
 the first in getting his ship ready 
 equipped ( Demosth. de Trierarch. C.'o- 
 rona, p. 1228, 5), we must probably 
 understand neither the treasurer of 
 the trierarch, nor the treasurer of the 
 trireme-builders, but the pay-master 
 of war, to whom this duty is the most 
 suitable. 
 
 '^7 Pollux viii. 113; Harpocr. Suid. 
 Ilesych. Etym. Ammonius. 
 
 '''* Demosth. de Corona, p. 226, 22. 
 See below, chap. 13.
 
 en. VII.] 
 
 AND FOR THE THEORICA. 
 
 183 
 
 whereas in later periods not only was no addition made to the 
 treasure^ but the war-funds did not even receive the surplus 
 monies. The managers of the theoricon are not called trea- 
 surers, although they evidently had the charge of a fund; they 
 belonged to the number of officers of government, and were 
 among the principal authorities elected by cheirotonia'^': it 
 appears that their appointment took place about the time of 
 the great Dionysia in the city''"'. Their number is nowhere 
 mentioned, but there were most probably ten, one from each 
 tribe; for in an office of such importance as this it cannot be well 
 supposed that any other method of election was adopted. Their 
 appellation is variable {apxv ^'"^^ '^^ decdpcKw, 6 ivl to3 OecapLK^ 
 cov, oi iirl TO OecopiKov Ke^etporovrffMevoi, 6 eirl twv OecopcKwv 
 rerayfievos^ iirl rov OecopcKov KaraaTaOels^ decopiKrj dp^rj, 
 dpx^^y Twv 6ecopiK(ovy*\ To the original department of 
 manager of the theoricon were annexed, at the time when Eubu- 
 lus of Anaphlystus filled this situation, and had obtained the 
 public confidence in a high degree, many of the other branches of 
 the administration, particularly the control of the public reve- 
 nues, the office of apodectae, the making of wharfs, of the arse- 
 nal, the construction of roads (the latter perhaps in some 
 degree because they were connected with the passage of proces- 
 sions), and nearly all the other duties of the administration, as 
 ^schines informs us'*^: in his capacity of manager of the the- 
 oricon, Demosthenes was also inspector of the building of the 
 walls {reix^'TroLosi) ^*^', and from the same cause Eubulus appears 
 to have superintended the ship-building^". 
 
 The extent of their power in such corrupt times cannot 
 appear in the least surprising. The theoricon promoted the 
 private interest of the citizens, and therefore the assembly 
 passed a decree by which they conferred extensive influence on 
 any person who had either the will or the ability to fill the 
 purses of individuals at the expense of the public. The Athe- 
 
 ^^ ^schin. c. Ctesiph. p. 416, 418. 
 
 *^ Petit Leg. Att. iii. 2, 35. 
 
 ^*'^ ^sch. lit sup. Demosth. de Co- 
 rona, p. 264, 10 ; p. 243, 27 ; p. 266, 22 ; 
 Lex. Seg. p. 264 ; Suidas and the Ety- 
 
 mologist. 
 
 ^*'^ Mschva.. ut Slip. p. 417 sqq. 
 
 ^^3 ^schin. ibid. p. 419, 425; 
 mosth. de Corona, p. 243, 266. 
 
 >** Dinarch. c. Demosth. p. G6, 
 
 De-
 
 184 
 
 FUNDS FOR THE THEORICA. 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 nian people reseml)led a tyrant, and the funds of the theoricon 
 were analogous to his private purse; if a tyrant desired to have, 
 for the gratification of his own pleasures, a private purse which 
 should never be empty, he would take care to invest the 
 managers of it with great power, and would leave to the branches 
 of the administration only just so much of the public revenue 
 as should not interfere with the proper supply of the privy 
 purse. This contrivance of the ochlocracy was abolished 
 between Olymp. 110, 2 (b.c. 339), and 112, 3 (b.c. 330), by a 
 decree proposed by Hegemon'^'. 
 
 At what time the managers of the theoricon were the 
 assessors of the poletse, is not mentioned; but it is not necessary 
 to suppose that they only performed this duty in the time of 
 their extended authority. For since the surplus money of the 
 administration was in time of peace always set apart for the 
 theoricon, and to the administration duties and taxes raised 
 in Athens were regularly assigned, while confiscated property 
 might appear to belong more peculiarly to the theoricon, it is 
 possible that this regulation was made when the office of 
 manager of the theorica was originally instituted. 
 
 Chapter VIII. 
 
 The Clerks and Checking-Clerks. System of Public Accounta- 
 bility and Audit, 
 
 From the multiplicity of the offices, it is evident that the 
 quantity of writing to be perform.ed must have been conside- 
 rable; the disbursements and receipts were to be entered, and 
 particularly the respective purposes to which the monies were 
 assigned ; these, together with the acknowledgments of pay- 
 ment, were to be noted doTVTi ; and finally, the accounts were to 
 be passed. All these duties came within the department of the 
 
 >^* Petit Leg. Att. iii. 2, 3G. In 
 Olymp. 110, 3, Demosthenes Avas both 
 inspector of the building of the Avails, 
 and manager of the theorica, but only 
 
 accidentally at the same time, as I have 
 already remaiked, Avithout the tAA'o 
 offices being at that period necessarily 
 united.
 
 CH. VIII.] THE CLERKS AND CHECKING-CLERKS. 185 
 
 secretary or clerk {ypafifjLaTev<;), Thus the treasurers of the 
 sacred monies, and the Amphictyons of Delos had their clerk^*% 
 and the same was also the case with subordinate or private 
 cashiers, as has been already remarked of Antimachus, the pay- 
 master of Timotheus. Citizens who were nominated to situa- 
 tions of this kind, were commonly persons of small fortune. 
 Public slaves {SrjfjLoacot) however, who had been educated at the 
 cost of the state, were also employed, and were sometimes 
 appointed for keeping accounts, of the generals for instance, and 
 the paymasters in times of war^^^, some as checking- clerks 
 {dvTLjpacpeU, contrarotulatores), as for example the clerks who 
 checked the accounts of the treasurers of the sacred monies, and 
 of the war-taxes, although Demosthenes thinks that each con- 
 tributor ought to perform for himself the office of a comp- 
 troller*'". A clerk in the employ of the state was never a slave; 
 and although the clerk Nicomachus is called by Lysias'^^ a 
 public slave {BTjfjLoo-io^;), this instance does not apply, for he was 
 only an under-clerk, and not one of the principal clerks or secre- 
 taries ; and the orator gives him that name in reference only to 
 his father; for he himself had been entered in the register of 
 the phratores, and consequently was a citizen. But the chief 
 reason why the Athenians preferred the public slaves for comp- 
 trolling the accounts, was, that they could be put to the torture, 
 and torture was considered as the surest means of eliciting the 
 truth'^°. Freemen could not be tortured upon the rack, nor 
 yet resident aliens or foreigners, as Gillies asserts ; for it was 
 prohibited by the decree of Scamandrius that any citizen should 
 be put to the torture for the purpose of examination'"; and 
 
 '« Inscript. 139, 141, 150, 158. 
 
 ^^7 Demosth. de Cherson. p. 101, 14, 
 and thence Philipp. iv. p. 137. Ulpian. 
 ad Demosth. Olynth. ii. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Androt. p. 615, 12 
 sqq. Lex. Seg. p. 197. 
 
 1^9 C. Nicom. p. 842, cf. p. 836, 837. 
 
 ^*" Demosth. c. Aphob. -^evdofx. p. 
 846, 7, p. 848, 8, p. 856, 20. That 
 more weight was given to the asser- 
 tions of slaves upon the rack than to 
 
 also shown by Hudtwalcker von den 
 Di'dteten, p. 51. 
 
 1" Andocid. de Myst. p. 22. The 
 torture of the concubine of Antiphon 
 {KaTTjy. (papfi. p. 615), provided that 
 she was a free woman, which is not cer- 
 tain, must be considered as a punish- 
 ment, and not as a means of exami- 
 nation. Against the assertion made 
 in the text, that freemen in Attica 
 could not be put to the torture, may 
 
 the sworn testimony of freemen, is ' be adduced a passage in Antip on (de
 
 186 THE CLERKS AND CII ECKING-CLERKS. [bK. II. 
 
 what Lysias says of Theodotus, a youth of Platsese, that he 
 might have been put to the torture '*% must be the rather con- 
 sidered as an exception, as the Platseans were citizens. 
 
 Besides these subordinate checking-clerks, there were others 
 of a superior class, who have sometimes been confounded with 
 the secretaries or clerks. It is difficult to obtain a clear know- 
 ledge of these officers at Athens ; in the mean time thus far is 
 certain, that there were three public clerks, as we learn from 
 Suidas'". Pollux^'* gives a more exact account ; one was chosen 
 by lot by the senate in every prytanea, for the purpose of keep- 
 ing the writings and decrees, and is the officer who prefixed his 
 name to the decrees according to the form which was in use 
 before the archonship of Euclid: of this secretary Aristotle 
 had, according to Harpocration^^', treated at length : the second 
 was elected by the senate by cheirotonia for the laws ; a third, 
 elected by the people, was the public reader in the senate and 
 the assembly. The first in an inscription of the time of the 
 Emperors is called the clerk according to the prytanea {ypafi- 
 fiarevs Kara Trpvraveiavy^^, where it is not so easy to perceive 
 why he should be enumerated among the aeisiti, as one should 
 rather have expected that he would only have had the privilege 
 of being fed in the prytaneum for a single prytanea ; a fresh 
 one was appointed in every prytanea, and the name of the clerk 
 of the first pr^-tanea was added to the decrees before the archon- 
 ship of Euclid, and was frequently made use of to designate 
 the year'*^ Harpocration states that it was the duty of this 
 
 Herod, caede, p. 729), in which it is I ^*^ ^iii. 98, ypafifiarevs, 6 Kara npv- 
 stated that a freeman was tortured at raveiav icKijpcodeh imb rrjs ^ovXtjs inX 
 Mytilene: but whether a Mytilensean ; ra [ra] ypafifxara (f)v\dTT€iv kol to, 
 or a foreigner, whether according to j yj/TjcpicrfxaTay Koi erepos errl tovs vop-ovs 
 
 the Lesbian or Athenian law, cannot 
 be decided. 
 
 "* ApoL c. Sunon. p. 153. What 
 Reiske says upon this passage does not 
 remove the difficulty. 
 
 '^^ Suidas, KkrjpciiToX be {ypapfiarels) 
 T}(Tav TOP apiBp.ov rpeis ypacfiovres ra 
 drjuoaia. Ovdevos 8e rjaav Kvpioi aXX' ^ 
 Tov ypd(f)€iu Koi dvayvwvai. The first 
 word, KXr;pu)Tot, is false in this general 
 sense. 
 
 vTTo TTJs 0ovXrjs xapoTovovfievof. 'O de 
 VTTO TOV brjpov alpedels ypapfxarevs dva- 
 yiv<ii(TK€i tS drjpco koi rfj ^ovXfj. A 
 ypapfiarevs ttjs /3ovX^y occurs in De- 
 mosth. pro Corona, p. 238, 14, and rod 
 drjpov in the third decree in the Lives 
 of the Ten Orators. 
 
 155 jjj y^ ypapfiarevs. 
 
 *^^ Chandl. Inscript. ii. 55, 2. 
 
 '*7 Vid. ad Inscript. 147 ct 7«.
 
 CH. Vlll.] THE CLERKS AND CIIECKIXG-CLERKS. 
 
 187 
 
 officer to check the public accounts'*^ ; but he doubtless con- 
 founds him with the checking-clerk. The second appears to be 
 the clerk of the senators {ypa/x/jLarevs tojv ^ovXevrojv) occurring 
 in inscriptions'*^, of whom I have nothing more to say than that 
 he is never mentioned among the aeisiti, but always among the 
 prytanes. Lastly, the third clerk is called the clerk of the 
 state {ypafjLfjLaTevs ttjs iroXecos), or of the senate and the people 
 {Trj9 ffov\rj<; koX tov hrjfiovY^^, and he is placed in inscriptions 
 among the aeisiti. 
 
 These ofiScers had an under-clerk {v7roypafi/jLaT€vs) : and a 
 considerable number of such persons were used even in the 
 ancient days of Athens, some of whom were employed in the 
 higher, and some in the inferior and subordinate offices'®^ ; the 
 checking-clerks were however different from these superior 
 secretaries or clerks, as we have already seen in the case of the 
 inferior. A checking-clerk of the senate [avrcypacfievs ttjs 
 /3ov\rjs) is quoted by Harpocration out of Aristotle^s State of 
 Athens' ^=^, and a checking-clerk without any farther specification 
 frequently occurs in ancient inscriptions, and always among the 
 
 '^^ Kaj TO. a)Oia iravra avTiypcKperai 
 Kol TrapaKd6r)Tai ttj /SovX^. The con- 
 fusion with the checking-clerk is e\i- 
 dent from the words of Pollux viii. 
 98, where it is said of him, kul navra 
 dvT€ypd(j)€TO 7rapaKa6T)ij.€vo5 ttj ^ovKfj. 
 This had been remai-ked by Valesius 
 in his notes to Harpocration, against 
 whom Kiihn's objections (ad Poll. viii. 
 98,) prove nothing. 
 
 ^^^ Chandl. u. 55, 1, 2, 3, 4. Spon 
 Ti-avek, vol. iii. in the inscription 
 belonging to the second volume p. 
 116 sqq. That he may not be con- 
 sidered the same as the clerk according 
 to the Prytaneia, the distinction be- 
 tween them in Chandl. ii. 55, 2, should 
 be observed. There are likewise many 
 other similar inscriptions, in which 
 this clerk of the senators and the 
 others occur. 
 
 ^^^ Thucyd. \\\, 10, and the inscrip- 
 tions just quoted. Besides Valesius, 
 authorities have been collected upon 
 
 this subject by Meursius Lect. Att. >i. 
 25 ; Petit, iii. 2, 28; Barthe'lemy Me'm. 
 de I'Acad. des Inscriptions, vol. XLviii. 
 p. 345. The xmoypapip.arev5 occurs in 
 the inscriptions already quoted; in 
 that published by Spon the editor in- 
 correctly reads HPOrPAMMATEYS. 
 : ^^^ Antiph. de Choreut. p. 792; De- 
 mosth. proTorona, p. 314, 7, xmoypap.- 
 fxareveip Koi xmr)peTc1v rotv apxibiois, 
 Lysias c. Nicom. p. 864, ter. 
 
 ^^^ Harpocrat. in v. dvriypacfjevs' 6 
 Ka$i,crTdp.evos en\ riov Kora^aXkovTOiV 
 Tivd TTj TTo'Xet ■)(^pr]jxaTa, cocrre dvriypd- 
 (f)€a6ai TavTcu Aijfxoadevqs iv t(o kutu 
 ^AudpoTicovos (a passage wliich is not 
 to the point, as it relates to subor- 
 dinate checking-clerks), koI AiV;^tj/7/s 
 €V Ta Kara KTrjcrKpavTOs. AittuI de 
 rjcrav dvTtypa(f)€7s, 6 fievTiis dioiKfjaecoSf 
 as (pTjGi ^iXoxopos' 6 de ttjs ^ovXrjs, cos 
 ' ApicrTOTeXT]s iv ^ K6rjvaia>v TToXireia, 
 The whole passage is also in Suidas.
 
 188 
 
 THE CLERKS AND CHECKING-CLERKS. [bK. II. 
 
 aeisiti. According to PoUux*^^ he was in ancient times elected 
 and afterwards chosen by lot : the checking-clerk of the senate 
 is also mentioned by Suidas'", as well as by the Scholiast to 
 Aristophanes'", who however confounds him wdth the clerk. 
 According to Pollux his duty was to sit in the senate and exer- 
 cise a general control ; a statement which may perhaps be true, 
 but that the duty which Harpocration attributes to the check- 
 ing-clerk, of comptrolling the receipts of the revenues, refers 
 to this office, is evident, the taxes having been paid in presence 
 of the senate. Lastly it is manifest that ^schines'^^ alludes to 
 this officer, when he remarks that the state had a checking- 
 clerk elected by cheirotonia, w^ho kept an account of the reve- 
 nues for the people in each prytanea, until this situation was 
 united with the office of the theoricon, by w^hich means the 
 duties of the apodectge, and the checking of the accounts, were 
 injudiciously placed in the same hands. Besides this checking- 
 clerk for monies received, there was also a checking-clerk of the 
 highest authority for disbursements, viz., the treasurer of the 
 administration, who w^as called the checking-clerk of the admi- 
 nistration {avTLrfpa(f>evs ttjs BioLKTjaecosj^^^ It is probable that 
 all clerks and checking-clerks (and certainly the under-clerks) 
 were prohibited from holding the same office twice'®% i. e., not 
 for two successive years, and it was necessary that a new person 
 should be appointed after the interval of a year. 
 
 '«=* viii. 98. Cf. Lex. Seg. p. 190, 26. 
 
 ^^* In V. ypafxfiarevs, where see 
 Kiister's note. Compare also Lex. 
 Seg. p. 185, IC. 
 
 ^" Eq. 1253. The following is the 
 whole of this corrupt passage: eVt Se 
 drjfxov (6 ypaufxarevs) v7roypa(f)€vs eXe- 
 y€TO. 6 8e Tov ^ovXevTijplov avriypa- 
 (pevs. dT]p.ocriov 8e yevopeuov eypa(f)ov 
 ufxcfiOTepoi TO. Xeyopeva. The latter 
 words, which are entirely devoid of 
 meaning, KUhn (ad Poll. viii. 98,) en- 
 deavours to correct ; but his correction 
 does not make any better sense. The 
 v7roypacf)€vs may be the vnoypap-fxarevs 
 of inscriptions. Petit also (ut sup.) 
 remaiks the confusion between the 
 
 clerk and checking-clerk in this pas- 
 sage. 
 
 ^«« Cont. Ctesiph. p. 417. Cf. Ulpian. 
 ad Demosth. c. Androt. ut sup. 
 
 ^^^ Philochorus ap. Harpocrat. ut 
 sup. and thence Suidas and Pollux 
 viii. 98, 99, according to the correct 
 emendation of Valesius upon Harpo- 
 cration. 
 
 ^'"' This is evidently the meaning of 
 the law in Lysias c. Nicom. p. 864 
 extr. v7roypafxp.aT€vaai ovk (^errrt, b\s 
 TOV avTou TTJ dpxfi Trj uvttj, although 
 the expression is somewhat singular; 
 but from the context it appears to me 
 that this is the only way in which it 
 can be understood.
 
 CH. VIII.] THE CLERKS AND CHECKING-CLERKS. 
 
 189 
 
 The public accounts being in this manner kept by the 
 clerks, and comptrolled by the checking- clerks, it was rendered 
 possible to make the scrutiny which was regularly entered into 
 at the expiration of every office. It is the essence of a demo- 
 cracy that every public officer should be responsible. Among 
 the distinguishing marks of a democratic authority, responsibi- 
 lity is one of the most prominent ; while in the aristocratical 
 and oligarchical states of antiquity, such as Sparta and 
 Crete, the highest offices, those in which the aristocracy and 
 oligarchy really existed, were subject to no responsibility. 
 Hence the obligation of rendering accounts for official conduct 
 prevailed to so great an extent at Athens : no person who had 
 had any share in the government or administration was exempted 
 from it; the senate of five hundred, even the Areopagus, at 
 least after the loss of their great power, were bound to render 
 an account : even the priests and priestesses were obliged to 
 produce accounts for the gifts {yipa) ; so also whole families, 
 such as the Eumolpidee and Cer^^ces, and even the trierarchs, 
 although the latter furnished everything at their own expense ; 
 no person who had not rendered his account could go abroad, 
 consecrate his property to a god, or even dedicate a sacred 
 offering; no one could make a will, or be adopted from one 
 family into another; in short, the state had a lien upon the 
 whole property of the individual until he had passed his scru- 
 tiny^". In the same manner no honorary gift or reward (such 
 for example as a crown) could be awarded to a person who had 
 not passed his scrutiny^''*'. The dicasts alone were free from 
 this obligation ^^^ 
 
 The authorities whose business it was to pass and examine 
 the accounts of public officers were, according to Aristotle' ^% 
 called in the Greek states, in some places evOvvot, in others 
 \o7tcrT«t, i^eraaTal, or o-vvrj<yopoi. That the logistae of the 
 Athenians were employed in matters of calculation is proved l)y 
 their name; the euthuni were in intimate connexion with them: 
 the difference between their duties was not, however, as is sup- 
 
 '" iEschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 405 sqq. 
 '70 ^sch. and Demosth. pro Corona. 
 '7' Arist. Vesp. 585. See Hudt- 
 
 walcker von den Diateten, p. 32. 
 
 >"^ In the last chapter of the 6th 
 book of the Politics.
 
 190 
 
 SYSTEM OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY 
 
 [bK. XL 
 
 posed by some, that the logistse had authority in those cases only 
 which concerned the administration of public money, while 
 the euthuni acted in all other cases ; but all questions belonged 
 indiscriminately to either authority. In the examinations of 
 persons who either had or had not the management of money, 
 the logistse, after the account had been rendered before them 
 and the secretary (probably of the senate and the people), 
 brought the cause into court, where they gave out by means of 
 the crier that they were ready to hear any accusation'^'. The 
 intimate connexion between the two offices is strikingly proved 
 by a decree in Andocides, in which mention is made of those 
 whose accounts were found unsatisfactory in the logisteria by 
 the euthuni or the assessors, and affording ground for an indict- 
 ment'^* : lastly, evOvva is often used in speaking of the logistae 
 and XoyLo-fjLo^ in speaking of the euthuni ; and the Etymologist 
 says'" that in his time those were called logistte who formerly 
 had borne the name of euthuni. The distinction between them 
 had been explained by Aristotle in the Constitution of 
 Athens'^® ; but the grammarians do not give any precise infor- 
 mation upon this point. According to Harpocration'", there 
 were ten logistee, to whom every person gave an account of his 
 proceedings within thirty days after the expiration of his office ; 
 and the same number of euthuni, whose duties were precisely 
 the same. All authorities agree in stating that the logistoe and 
 euthuni were both ten in number'^". Pollux gives us an 
 
 '73 ^schin. c. Ctesiph. p. 403 sqq. 
 Demosth. pro Corona, p. 266, 9. 
 
 '^'^ De Myst. p, 37, oaoiv evdvvai 
 Tives elcri KaTeyvaxrfxevai iv rols Xoyi- 
 (TTTjplois (see Lysias c. Polystr. p. 672,) 
 vTTo rail/ evOvvcov ff rtov Tvapebpiov. The 
 last words appear to be an interpre- 
 tation which has crept into the text : 
 but I do not venture to stiike them 
 out, as assessors of the euthuni are 
 mentioned. 
 
 *7^ In V. €vdvvoi, from whom Pho- 
 tius and Zonaras took ; in the latter of 
 which grammarians read UXdroov No- 
 
 '^'^ A p. Harpocrat. 
 
 '7'' In V. Xoyiaral and €v6vvot, and 
 thence Suidas and Photius in v. Xo- 
 yiaToi and fvQvvoi^ also Lex. Seg. 
 p. 245, 276. The person is called eu- 
 Ovvos and €v6vvj]s, in the plural €v6v- 
 voi and cudvvai, the proceeding is t) 
 €v$vva, (see the law in Demosth. c. 
 Timocrat. p. 717,19, where however it 
 is falsely accented cvdvpa), in the 
 plural €v6vpai; likewise ^ evBvjnj, 
 which the grammarians quote as tlie 
 common form, but which is perhaps of 
 later origin. 
 
 '^^ Etymol. in v. evBvvoL, Pliotius, 
 and Pollux viii. 45. From Pollux 
 viii. 99 ; Petit iii. 2. 6, concludes that
 
 CH. VIII.] 
 
 AND AUDIT. 
 
 191 
 
 important addition, viz., " that the senate chose the logistae by 
 lot, in order to attend/' as he expresses himself, " upon the offi- 
 cers of the administration,'' that is, to watch over their conduct; 
 " but the euthuni were chosen in addition, Uke the assessors of 
 the nine archons'^^'^ 
 
 What constituted the difference of their duties can even in 
 general be arrived at only by conjecture. The logistse were the 
 chief persons, and to them the accounts were delivered, into the 
 correctness of which they examined ; they also, as the calcu- 
 lators of the state, superintended the payment of the public 
 debts'^". But while the accounts were being examined {Xoyia-- 
 yLto9 or \6y09), or even afterwards, if an accuser came forward 
 
 there were two other logistae : but 
 this passage refers, as has been al- 
 ready observed, to the two checkiDg- 
 clerks. 
 
 *79 Pollux viii. 99, 100, where he 
 Bays, 01 6e €v6vvoi, aanep ol TrapeSpoi 
 Tols ivvia ap^ovcri, TrpocraipovvTat,. 
 Comp. upon this point Petit ut sup. 
 [The Author has since referred the 
 first part of this passage from Pollux 
 to the dvTiypa(f)€'is or checking- clerks, 
 and adopted the statement of the 
 grammarians, (Lex. Seg. p. 276, 17 ; 
 Etym. Mag. p. 569, 31,) that the lo- 
 gistae were appointed by lot, Rheinisches 
 Museum, vol. i. p. 82. It is however 
 singular that the author, as well as his 
 antagonist, should have missed one of 
 the most explicit passages on the sub- 
 ject, viz., in a grammarian published 
 by ^Mr. Dobree at the end of Photius, 
 p. 672. AoyicTTai' Koi crvvrjyopor 'Apicr- 
 TOTeXrjs iv ttj 'Adrjvaitov TToXtreta ovrco 
 Xeyei' Xoytorai de alpovvrai bcKa, ivap 
 oXs diaXoyi^ovrai naaai ai apxal fd re 
 \rjnp.aTct Koi ras yeyevrjpevas dandvas' 
 Koi (iWois (aXXoi) deKa crvvqyopoLS 
 {(TVVTjyopoi), oItlvcs avvavaKplvovcn tov- 
 TOts. Koi oi ras dOvvas didouTes rrapa 
 TOVTOis dvaKpivovres 7rpa>T0V, eira icpiev- 
 rai els TO diKao-Trjpiop ds eva Kal cf). 
 This passage seems to show that the 
 logistae wei-e not chosen by lot (alpovv- 
 
 rai, not KkrjpovvTai), and it is also a 
 strong negative proof of the identity of 
 the logistae and euthuni. The o-vvrj- 
 yopot are mentioned in another gram- 
 marian quoted by the author in note 
 186, (TvvTjyopoi cipx^opTcs rjcrav AcXj;pa)rot, 
 ot rots' Xoyicrrals e^orjdovv npos rag 
 evOvvas Ta)U dp^dvrcou riva dp^qv. 
 Here however it is stated that the 
 (TvvTjyopoi were chosen by lot: perhaps 
 in the former passage we should read 
 KKrjpovvTai for alpovvrai. These avvfj' 
 yopoi therefore seem to have been 
 quite distinct from the public advo- 
 cates (although the contrary is 
 maintained by Schomann, de Comi- 
 tiis, p. 108); they were probably the 
 same as the ndpebpoi mentioned by 
 Andocides and others. The public 
 advocates are stated by Photius (in 
 V. crvvrjyopol) to have been nomi- 
 nated by election (xeiporovla). In the 
 passage also from the Politics quoted 
 in note 172, Aristotle mentions Xoyia-' 
 rai, evdvvoi, and (rvvrjyopoi as syno- 
 nymous terms. — Transl.] 
 
 '^<' Inscript. 76, § 4, Xoyos and Xo- 
 yiapos is the account, the evdvvrj or 
 defence of the account was commonly 
 connected with it, as e. g. in Inscript. 
 76, § 8; iEschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 397, 
 403, &c.
 
 192 
 
 SYSTEM OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY [bK. II. 
 
 (who was however obliged to appear within a certain time^^', 
 i. e. within thirty days after the expiration of the office), ques- 
 tions were put and answers required concerning the correctness 
 of the statements {evOvva), a point which it would be difficult 
 and tedious to explain: now it is for this, that the euthuni 
 appear to have been appointed as assistants to the logistse, as 
 may be inferred from their name. The euthuni or their asses- 
 sors might decide that the account was unsatisfactory, that 
 money had been embezzled, bribes received, &c.; when such was 
 the case, the affair was brought before a court of justice, in the 
 same manner as when a public accuser came forward' ^^. The 
 
 i»i Pollux viii. 45. 
 
 '82 In the arclionship of Alexias in 
 01}Tnp. 93, 4 (B.C. 405), by the decree 
 of Patrocleides, the public debtors 
 were remitted their debts up to the 
 end of the preceding year (Olymp. 93, 
 3, in the archonship of Callias), and 
 those who had been condemned to 
 Atimia for non-payment were restored 
 to their civil rights. By this law, par- 
 don was at the same time extended to 
 those o(T(ov evdvval rtves elcri KaTcyvcocr- 
 fxevai ep Tois XoyicTTTjpiois vno rcov ev- 
 Bvvcov Tj Ta>v TrapeBpciiv, rj fxrjTTco el(TT]y- 
 fievac (Is TO 8iKaaTT)piov ypacfiai rives 
 fieri TTfpi Ta)v evBvvcoVf with the addi- 
 tion of the date els top uvtop tovtop 
 Xpovov. For the explanation of this 
 passage I subjoin the following re- 
 marks. It was not only the public 
 debts and Atimia that were remitted, 
 to which the debtors had become sub- 
 ject by a punishment wliich had been 
 previously adjudged, but it was also 
 enacted that the actions against public 
 officers which were at that time insti- 
 tuted on account of incorrect accoimts, 
 should be disannulled, i. e. that the 
 causes which had not been yet de- 
 cided, but were still depending, should 
 be quashed. These however were of 
 two kinds. In the first place the eu- 
 thuni or their assessors in the exami- 
 nation of the accounts had decided 
 that certain public officers were guilty. 
 
 and had determined to institute pro- 
 ceedings against them {evBvpai Karey- 
 va>ap.evaL ip Tots\oyi(rTr]pLois\ although 
 by these means, as a court of justice 
 could alone pass sentence, no punish- 
 ment had as yet been assigned : or an 
 accuser had brought forward com- 
 plaints with regard to the accounts of 
 the public servants, who were under- 
 going the scrutiny, but the accusations 
 were still in the hands of the presi- 
 dents of the courts of justice and not 
 yet brought before the court itself 
 {ypa(Pa\ nepl to)P evdvpcop prj-rrco ela-rjy- 
 p-epai els to biKaaTrjpiop): both kinds 
 of cases were to be put an end to. 
 Among the fii'st class of cases those 
 also were included which had not yet 
 been brought before the court of jus- 
 tice, which as being self-evident are 
 therefore not mentioned ; but the 
 former class is particularly noticed, 
 because the persons who were com- 
 prised in it had been condemned by 
 the previous decision of a public office, 
 and therefore seemed to be more 
 inculpated than the others. It may 
 be also asked why those persons are 
 not mentioned whose causes subse- 
 quent upon the decision of the eu- 
 thuni had been brought before the 
 court previously to the end of the pre- 
 ceding year, but had not been decided. 
 No cases however of this kind could 
 liave existed, because when the cause
 
 CH. VIII.] 
 
 AND AUDIT. 
 
 193 
 
 proceedings which belonged to this stage (which are even here 
 called evOvvaLY''^ were instituted by the chief authority, the 
 logistae; who conducted the actions, and composed the tribunal 
 which gave judgment in the case'^*. In bringing on the action 
 it is possible that the euthuni again assisted the chief antho- 
 rity : and perhaps too, as Pollux asserts, they enforced the pay- 
 ment of embezzled monies and fines, instead of the practores. 
 Photius^'' alone states that each euthunus had two assessors, 
 but he is supported by the words of Andocides. Lastly, the 
 public advocates {o-vvrjyopoi) afforded assistance to the logist8e^"^ 
 Any person who neglected to render his account could be prose- 
 cuted by a particular action {BUtj dXoylovY^K 
 
 From what has been said it is evident that there was no 
 want at Athens of well-conceived and strict regulations; but 
 what is the use of provident measures, where the spirit of the 
 administration is bad? Men have at all times been unjust and 
 covetous and unprincipled, and above all the Greeks distin- 
 guished themselves for the uncontrolled gratification of their 
 own desires, and their contempt for the happiness of others. 
 
 had been once brought before court, 
 the decision immediately ensued, with- 
 out the defendant being able to delay 
 it by objections or cross suits. 
 
 '^3 Pollux ut sup. 
 
 ^^* iEsch. c. Ctesiph. p. 395 sqq. and 
 408 ; Suidas in v. €v6vpt], Lex. Ehet. 
 (Seg. p. 245, also Lex. Seg. p. 310, C); 
 EtjTn. and Phot, in the passages 
 quoted by Ruhnken ad Tim. p. 126. 
 See Petit ut sup. 
 
 '^^ EvBvvos' apxh V" '■^^' '^^ €Kd(TTr]S 
 fie (jyvXiis eva KXrjpoixrt, tovtco be dvo 
 TTapebpovs: in which passage the ev6vvoi 
 are falsely represented as chosen by 
 lot, which is only true of the logistae. 
 Hesychius in v. €v6vvas only speaks 
 incidentally of the assessors of the 
 archons, the word €v3vpas occun-ing 
 in a passage of Aristotle concerning 
 the latter officers: no one should 
 therefore be led into error by tliis 
 article. 
 
 '«« Lex. Seg. p. 301. 
 
 '^7 Suidas, Hesychius, Etymol. in v. 
 uXoylov StKT/, Pollux viii. 54. To ap- 
 prove the accounts is called ras cvBvvas 
 iuLo-qfiaiveaOai. Deraosth. pro Co- 
 rona, p. 310, 21. 'Emar}p.aive(r6ac 
 means to approve, eVaii/eti/ (cf. ^sch. 
 TTfpl Trapanpea^. p. 230. Harpocrat. 
 in V. €7naT]fiaiv€(rOai, and thence Suidas 
 and Zonaras, p. 848, cf. p. 830, and 
 the editor's note) because that which 
 is signed and sealed is approved of by 
 him to whom the decision belongs : 
 however it may be possible that after 
 the accounts had been found to be 
 correct by the proper authorities, the 
 testimony of their correctness was 
 added in writing and confirmed by a 
 seal, so that eTnarjfxaiveaBai ras evBvvas 
 may signify the approval of them 
 which was vouched by being sealed iu 
 this manner.
 
 194 SYSTEM OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY [bK. II. 
 
 If any competent judge of moral actions will contemplate their 
 character without prejudice, and unbiassed by their high intel- 
 lectual endowments, he will find that their private life was 
 unstable, and devoid of virtue; that their public life was a 
 tissue of restless intrigues and evil passions ; and, what was the 
 worst of all, that there existed to a far greater degree than in 
 the Christian world, a want of moral principle, and a harshness 
 and cruelty in the popular mind. The display of noble actions, 
 it is true, has ceased, and will never re-appear with the same 
 brilliancy; but the principles of the majority of mankind have 
 been elevated, even if we allow that some distinguished indi- 
 viduals in ancient times were as pure as the most exalted cha- 
 racters of modern days; and in this general elevation consists 
 the progress of mankind. 
 
 When we consider then the principles of the Greeks, which 
 are sufficiently seen from their historians and philosophers, it 
 cannot be a matter of surprise that fraud used by public officers 
 at Athens against the state, was of common occurrence : in the 
 early times of the republic Aristides, the contemporary of The- 
 mistocles, complained of it; it was even the common opinion 
 that there existed a certain prescriptive right to the commission 
 of this fraud, and a person who had scruples on the subject 
 was censured for his too great strictness '^^ Every where 
 we meet with instances of embezzlement of money by public 
 officers; even the sacred property was not secure from sacri- 
 legious hands. The Romans had at least a period in which 
 fidelity and honesty were practised and esteemed: but among 
 the Greeks these qualities will be sought for in vain. The 
 former were bound by a solemn oath to administer without 
 peculation the money entrusted to their care; "but if in 
 Greece," says the faithful Polybius'^% "the state entrusts to 
 any one only a talent, and if it has ten checking-clerks, and as 
 many seals and twice as many witnesses, it cannot ensure his 
 honesty." The officers of finance were therefore not unfre- 
 quently condemned to death or to loss of property and imprir 
 sonment; sometimes indeed unjustly, when money had acci- 
 
 ^^^ Plutarch. Aristid. 4. i89 ^,j g^^
 
 CH. VIII.] AND AUDIT. 195: 
 
 dentally been lost'*^; but the logistse allowed themselves to be 
 disgracefully bribed in order to enable the offender to evade the 
 legal penalty^^'. 
 
 Even the great Pericles does not appear to have been free 
 from the charge of peculation, if at least the story is true which 
 represents Alcibiades to have said, on hearing that Pericles was 
 occupied in preparing his accounts for the people, that he would 
 be better occupied in endeavouring to render none at air*^ The 
 comic poets, who undermined the fame of every distinguished 
 person, have also brought against him charges which are doubt- 
 less exaggerated; for example, Aristophanes in the comedy of 
 the Clouds misunderstands and ridicules an item in the account 
 of Pericles which he had rendered in his capacity of general, 
 although in this instance he was free from all blame. The 
 truth is that he had charged 10 talents, without specifying the 
 particular object to which they had been applied; but the 
 charge was allowed by the people, as it was well known that 
 they had been used for purposes of bribery, and that the names 
 of those who had received them could not be mentioned with- 
 out oiFending Pleistonax the king of Sparta, and the harmost 
 Cleandrides'^^ There is however a very general tradition that 
 Pericles was in great difficulties with his accounts. Before the 
 breaking out of the Peloponnesian war, Phidias the sculptor 
 was subjected, by means as, it appears, of a conspiracy, to an 
 examination respecting some gold which he was accused of 
 having embezzled' ^^; on that occasion Pericles extricated him- 
 self and Phidias from the difficulty. But other attacks were 
 made upon him for the purposes of annoyance; and at last 
 when the Athenians were dissatisfied with his lavish expendi- 
 
 '^^ Comp. e. g. Demosth. c. Timoth. 
 p. 1187, 1197; c. Timocrat. p. 742 sqq. 
 
 '3> ^schin. c. Timarch. p. 126. 
 
 '^^ Plutarch. Alcib. 7; Diod. xii. 38. 
 . '^3 Aristoph. Nub. 856, and the 
 Scholiast, and thence Suidas in v. 
 8eoVy *E(^opoi, els deoVy els to 8€0V, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 234. The Scholiast of 
 Aristophanes says 20, Suidas in one j other things, 
 place 15, in another 50 talents ; I have 
 
 followed the statement of Plutarch 
 (Pericl. 22, 23) which has greater pro- 
 bability. 
 
 ' ^* Plutarch. Pericl. 3 1 . This cause 
 instituted against Pericles is alluded 
 to by Plato Gorg. p. 516 A. where see 
 Heindorf: the Scholiast of Aristo- 
 phanes and Suidas confound this with 
 
 o 2
 
 196 SYSTEM OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY [bK. II. 
 
 ture'®^, they required an account of his financial administration. 
 The importance of this transaction is evident from the proceed- 
 ings which were proposed for it: the account was to have been 
 referred to the prytanes; and according to the decree of Dra- 
 contides, the judges were to vote from the altar upon the Acro- 
 polis, which was the most solemn method of deciding. This 
 last ceremony was dispensed with by the interference of Hag- 
 non, and it was directed that fifteen hundred judges should sit 
 in judgment upon this case, in which it was uncertain whether 
 there had been peculation or some other ofFence^^^ In order to 
 put an end to this contest, in which he was in danger of falling 
 a sacrifice both to party rage and his own dishonesty, Pericles is 
 said to have engaged his country in a war^®^; a severe accusa- 
 tion, which however will be in some degree diminished, if it is 
 considered that several causes contributed, and that this selfish 
 motive might only have added strength to other inducements. 
 I am the less inclined wholly to acquit Pericles of this charge, 
 because Aspasia is also said to have contributed to the under- 
 taking of the Samian war. 
 
 In order that the accounts rendered by persons who had 
 filled public offices should have the greatest possible publicity, 
 and that it should be in the power of every one to bring for- 
 ward accusations, these accounts were, like the decrees, engraved 
 on stone and exposed in public. Thus Lycurgus set up the 
 account of his administration before the wrestling-school which 
 he had built a short time previously'®^; a fragment of a similar 
 account of the treasurer of the administration and manager of 
 the public revenue, and probably of this very one made by 
 Lycurgus, has been preserved to our days^. In like manner the 
 treasurers of the goddess and of the other gods were obliged to 
 have an account of what they had received, disbursed, and 
 
 '" Plutarch. Pericl. 14. 
 
 '^« Plutarch, ibid. 32. 
 
 '»7 Pint. ibid. 31, 32 : Diod. xii. 38 
 
 war, and Pleyne (Antiquarische Auf- 
 satze, i. p. 188 sq.) who lias well exa- 
 mined the question. Concerning the 
 
 sqq.; Aristoph. Pac.604 sqq. andSchol. ' Samian war see Plutarch. Pericl. 25. 
 Concerning the difficulties in arranging i '®'' Life of Lycurgus at the end, in 
 the date see Dodwell Annal. Thucyd. } the Lives of the Ten Orators, 
 in the sixth year of the Peloponnesian » Inscript. 157.
 
 en. VIII.] 
 
 AND AUDIT. 
 
 197 
 
 delivered to their successors, engraved upon stone and set up 
 in the AcropoHs'^^: Chandler has published three inscriptions 
 of this kind, and saw still more in the Parthenon""", and some 
 have been brought to England by Lord Elgin. Several docu- 
 ments of this description, some money-accounts, some lists of 
 treasures belonging to temples, delivered over to other trea- 
 surers, which were accurately weighed, have come down to our 
 days; among which may be mentioned the remarkable account 
 given by the Amphictyons of Delos, of their revenues, ex- 
 penses, and outstanding debts. Lastly, we know that the 
 poletse also fixed up lists of confiscated property {BrjjjLtoTrpara), 
 (whether before or after the sale is uncertain,) upon tablets of 
 stone, some in the Acropolis, some at Eleusis^"', and doubtless 
 also in other places; and probably a fragment of an inscription 
 now extant was a part of a document of this nature^. 
 
 Monuments of this kind are necessarily destroyed by length 
 of time; but it is much to be lamented that we should not be 
 possessed of those which had been collected by Greek antiqua- 
 rians. The Attic epigrams of Philochorus w^ere probably only 
 j^oetical inscriptions; but the traveller Polemon, who from his 
 fondness for inscriptions had acquired the surname of Stelocopas 
 {arrjXoKOTras), wrote four books on the sacred offerings upon 
 
 '9« Inscript. 76, § 7, 8. 
 
 ^°° Chandl. Syllab. p. 17, of his In- 
 script. Antiq. besides those which 1 
 have published. The inedited inscrip- 
 tions occur in Lord Elgin's collection, 
 as stated by Visconti in his Me'moire, 
 No. 36, upon two sides of a stone, upon 
 one side of which there are forty, on 
 the other more than fifty lines, of the 
 writing before Euclid. The authori- 
 ties are the treasurers of sacred money 
 (^raniai Ta>v Upav ■)(^prjiiaraiv), the 
 articles enumerated partly weighed, 
 partly unweighed {aarad^xoi). The 
 first line contains the words ex Hava- 
 QTjvaidiv €S Uavadrjvaia : which is to be 
 explained from what is said in the text. 
 No. 37, also a fragment, written in the 
 ancient manner, upon both sides of the 
 stone, each of Avhich contains more 
 
 than forty lines. The first side begins 
 with eBldocrav top \6yov, the other with 
 H H H H A A. This inscription is 
 evidently allied to Nos. 109 and 141 ed. 
 Boeckh. No. 38, another fragment of 
 the same description in the ancient 
 manner of writing, written in the same 
 way. No. 46, a fragment of the same 
 kind as the two inscriptions just men- 
 tioned, but very imperfect : there are 
 forty-five lines remaining. No. 50, a 
 later inscription which contains a cata- 
 logue of treasures belonging to a tem- 
 ple of great length. Concerning these 
 inscriptions see also The Earl of Elgin's 
 Pursuits in Greece^ p. 17, 18. 
 
 *'»' Casaub. ad Athen. xi. p. 476 E. 
 Hemsterh. ad Poll. x. 96. 
 
 ^ Boeckh. Coip. Inscript. No. 161.
 
 198 
 
 SYSTEM 
 
 OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY, [bK. II. 
 
 the Acropolis"*, as well as copiously upon other inscriptions, 
 and collected decrees'"' Engraved upon stone, particularly at 
 Athens; a collection of decrees, most of them doubtless taken 
 from inscriptions, was given to the world by Craterus*"*. 
 Another collection of the registers of the demioprata was like- 
 wise extant, and is frequently quoted by Pollux in the tenth 
 book"*, and once by Athenseus; from this source the former 
 writer drew his information respecting the confiscated property 
 of Alcibiades"'; and in this collection of the demioprata there 
 were also accounts of the treasurers of the Acropolis concerning 
 the cession of the sacred treasures, probably from the work of 
 Polemon; among others one which by chance has come down 
 
 2"^ Athen. vi. 234 D, and Casaubon's 
 note. 
 
 ^^^ An example occurs in Athen. vi. 
 p. 234 E. From him also the inscrip- 
 tion in the Anaceum (p. 235 B) is no 
 doubt taken. 
 
 ^* Plutarch. Cim. 13. From some 
 such collection the decrees which occur 
 in the Lives of the Ten Orators are 
 borrowed. 
 
 ''^^ The tables of the goods sold or 
 confiscated by the state {to. dTjfjuoTrpaTo), 
 which were affixed in different places, 
 contained various articles of household 
 furniture, and are therefore often cited 
 by Pollux in his lOtli book, in which 
 he treats of utensils ; he himself had 
 not seen them, but followed a "vvritten 
 collection. Thus he mentions iv^oxKia 
 a-ih-qpa, where the v before /x betrays 
 the inscription (23); also 6vpa bid- 
 npia-Tos and 6upai avvdpopd^es C24) ; 
 from the confiscated property of Alci- 
 biades -x^apfCvq napaKoXXos Koi kXivtj 
 iip.(t)iKve(f)a\os (36); furthermore, Kve- 
 <f)dkov Katvbv and KvecpaXov naXaiov 
 (.39), XovTTjpiov Koi vnoaTarov (46, 79), 
 rf)idaKv\s, a wine vessel (74), Tpdne^a 
 fiovoKVKXos (f{l); likewise paintings, 
 Kai TTLva^ TToiKiXos ott' 6pocf)r]s Koi niva^ 
 (Tfpos yfypapptfos ; and plates or 
 "iTLvaKis fia^ypol (84), Kuvaarov and 
 
 KawcTTpov (86), XeKOS (87), p.axaipia 
 €X€(})dvTiva, fiaxaipia Kcpdriva, also, 
 as it seems, x^pvi^a, Xe^rjres, itpoxovSy 
 X^pvi^iov (89, 90), Kvpivo6r)KT) (93), 
 apTTjKia o^eXicTKOiv (96), fioXv^doKpa' 
 TevToi, or leaden stands for spits (96-7), 
 (TKd(Pr] iiaKpa and (TKd(fiT) arpoyyvXr] (1 03 ) , 
 devTTjp^lOb), Tjdpos vTTOKprjrqpidios (I08)y 
 mere kitchen and table utensils; also 
 i other implements, as Kocricii/o? kplOottoios 
 I (114), VTToXrjuiou (130), fKTruoTqpiov 
 I (135), Ki/Scoros BvpiboiTq (137), paKia 
 1 and KTjpcoTo. (150), KaXim-nipes Kopiv- 
 I Biovpyels (157), aXoii/ rpia r}p.i<j>6ppt.a 
 (169), napcoXevides (171 Jj KXipaKtou 
 (182), K€pap,os ^Attlkos and K€pap.6s 
 KopivOios (182). These examples suffi- 
 ciently prove the similarity of the 
 j inscriptions which were included in 
 the collection of the Demioprata, with 
 Inscript. No. 161, ed. Boeckh. ; al- 
 though it is not to be denied that lists 
 of offerings and temple utensils were 
 also included in it. It may be ob- 
 served that Pollux doubtless cited 
 many words from the Demioprata in 
 his 10th book, without mentioning 
 his authority; at least many words 
 occur in the inscription just quoted 
 which are also to be found in Pollux. 
 ^"^ Pollux X. 36.
 
 CH. IX.] PUBLIC REVENUE AND EXPENDITURE. 
 
 199 
 
 to our time and is now in England'^^ Probably the list of 
 the sacred offerings upon the Acropolis quoted by Pollux*°% 
 was set up during the archonship of Alcibiades, that is, a 
 memorial of the treasurer's accounts^ of whom he was the first, 
 borrowed from these demioprata. 
 
 Chapter IX. 
 
 How far a regular comparison of the Public Revenue and Expen- 
 diture was instituted. On the Heads of Expenditure, 
 
 But however essential the settlement of accounts may be to a 
 
 regular administration of finance, it is not of itself sufficient. 
 The first requisite is a correct estimate of the revenue and 
 expenditure, in order that the former may be sufficient to meet 
 the latter. It can hardly be said that this estimate was made 
 regularly in any Grecian state; at the same time they must 
 have been able from experience and a comparison of the public 
 accounts, to form a tolerable judgment as to the amount of the 
 regular income and expenditure, and how far the former was or 
 was not sufficient, and the latter necessary or superfluous. 
 Aristotle says*''^ '^ Whoever wishes to deliberate upon matters 
 of finance must be acquainted with the revenues of the state. 
 
 ^7 See the remark on 1. 37 of No. 
 loljin Corp. Inscript. Gr. vol. i. p. 
 242. 
 
 ^^^ 'Avaypa<pT] rcov ev 'AxpoTToXei dva- 
 BrjfMdTtov, X. 26. The quotations that 
 are made from this catalogue occur in 
 two inscriptions still extant. See 
 Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 150, and 
 the remark, vol. i. p. 236. There is 
 no mention of any Archon Alcibia- 
 des. Pollux probably confounded 
 the first treasurer of the goddess or 
 of the gods, whose name stood at 
 the head of the inscription, with the 
 archon. If Alcibiades had not been a 
 treasurer upon the Acropolis, how could 
 it have come to pass that he, as Plu- 
 tarch relates in the Life of Alcibiades, 
 
 had in his house many gold and silver 
 
 ornaments for processions belonging to 
 the state, which he used as his own 
 property; if he held the office of trea- 
 surer upon the Acropolis he would 
 have had the means of doing this. 
 The account given by Andocides (cont. 
 Alcib. p. 126, 127), is different from 
 this story of Plutarch taken from 
 Phseax, where he speaks of ornaments 
 for processions, which Alcibiades had 
 borrowed from the architheori of 
 Athens for the sake of his triumphal 
 festival. This has been also observed 
 by Ruhnken Hist. Crit. Orat. p. 138, 
 vol. viii. of Reiske's Orators. 
 
 •^«^ Rhet. i. 4; cf. Xenoph. Mem. 
 Socrat. iii. 6, 4 — 6.
 
 200 PUBLIC REVENUE AND EXPENDITURE. [bK. II. 
 
 what and how great they are; in order that if any branch of 
 them is deficient, it may be added, and if too small, it may be 
 increased. He should also know all the expenses of the state, 
 in order that if any one is superfluous, it may be retrenched, 
 and if too large, be curtailed. For wealth is augmented, not 
 only by increasing revenue, but by diminishing expenditure, 
 and these things a man cannot learn from his own individual 
 experience; but it is also necessary in order to deliberate upon 
 subjects of this nature that he should have the habit of inquir- 
 ing into the discoveries of others.^^ Here the questions are 
 clearly laid down which a minister at the head of the public 
 revenue should undertake to consider; it may, however, be 
 fairly questioned whether the Athenians always went correctly 
 to work in the difficult application of these simple principles. 
 The necessity, and afterwards the habits or convenience of the 
 people, introduced certain expenses; the time soon came when 
 the revenues were not sufficient to defray them, and then the 
 former were to be diminshed or the latter increased; of these 
 alternatives it must be supposed that they generally took the 
 latter, and this without previously making any correct estimate. 
 This was the case to a greater degree in their extraordinary 
 expenses, and after the public treasure had been exhausted, all 
 the great enterprises were checked by a want of supplies. 
 
 With regard to the Athenian revenue we have its amount at 
 difi'erent periods of the republic; but of that of the expenditure 
 we know but little, though it must have varied very much at 
 different times. I shall treat of the latter first; but as it is a 
 subject branching out into many different directions, it will for 
 that reason be impossible for me to give so complete and satis- 
 factory an account of it as of the revenue, and I must be con- 
 tent with touching upon the chief points. 
 
 The regular expenditure may be arranged under the follow- 
 ing heads: expenses of buildings, police, celebration of festivals, 
 donations to the people, pay for certain public services in time 
 of peace, maintenance of the poor, public rewards, and the pro- 
 viding of arms, ships, and cavalry, in time of peace. Extraor- 
 dinary expenses were occasioned by war, of which I shall speak 
 at the end of this book.
 
 CH. X.] THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 201 
 
 Chapter X. 
 
 The Public Buildings. 
 
 The public buildings, the magnificence and splendid execution 
 of which still excite astonishment even in their ruins, were con- 
 structed at so great an expense, that they could not have been 
 attempted without the treasure derived from the tributes: their 
 maintenance alone required a considerable standing expense. I 
 will only mention the building of the Piraeus by Themistocles, 
 the fortification of it together with the other harbours, the mar- 
 ket place of the Hippodamus, the theatre and the many temples 
 and sacred edifices, in the Pireeus; the wharfs, in which the 
 ships lay as it were under cover, cost 1000 talents, and after 
 having been destroyed in the Anarchy by the contractors for 
 three talents, were again restored and finally completed by 
 Lycurgus*'". A splendid edifice in the Pireeus was the arsenal 
 built by Philon and destroyed by Sulla [<7K€vo6rjKr], 67r\o6f]K7fY^\ 
 The fortifications of Athens were enormous ; besides the Acro- 
 polis, the city and the Piraeus with Munychia were respec- 
 tively fortified: the two latter embraced a circumference of 8 
 English miles, with walls 60 Grecian feet high, which The- 
 mistocles wished to make as much as double this height; and at 
 the same time so wide that two carriages could easily pass one 
 another upon them; they were built of square stones, without 
 cement, joined together with iron cramps; the city and the 
 harbour were also connected by the long walls, the longer of 
 which was equal to 40 stadia (5 English miles), the shorter 
 to 35, built upon marshy ground raised with stones. And 
 these immense works were restored after their destruction in 
 the time of the Thirty Tyrants: for which purpose the Atheni- 
 ans were, it is true, assisted by Persian money*'*. To these 
 were added in time of war, ramparts of earth, trenches, and 
 parapets, for the strengthening of the works: together with the 
 
 2^" Isocrat. Areopiig. 27 ; Meiirs. Fort. Att. vii. 
 2" Meurs. ibid. ^'^ Xenoph. Uelleii. iv. 8, 12.
 
 ^0§ 
 
 THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 fortification of smaller places in Attica. Thus Eleusis was for- 
 tified as being an ancient, and formerly an independent city; 
 also Anaphlystus, as we learn from Xenophon*'^ and Scylax; 
 so again Sunium was fortified in the Peloponnesian war^^% as 
 well as Thoricus*'* and CEnoe, a stronghold upon the Boeotian 
 frontier"^; together with the secure defences of Phyle*^^; lastly, 
 Aphidna and Rhamnus, which in the time of Philip, together 
 with Phyle, Sunium, and Eleusis were used as places of refuge*'^ 
 But how great was the number of splendid buildings which the 
 city and its environs contained; if we consider the spaces used 
 for the assembly, the courts of justice, and markets, the highly 
 ornamented porticos, the pompeum, prytaneum, tholus, senate- 
 house, and other buildings for the public offices: the innumera- 
 ble temples, the theatre, the odeum, wrestling-schools, gym- 
 nasia, stadia, hippodromes, aqueducts, fountains, baths, together 
 with the buildings belonging to them, &c.^'^ And again, how 
 great must have been the expense of the works upon the Acro- 
 polis. The entrance alone, the Propylaea, which occupied five 
 years in its construction, cost 2012 talents^^". Here too the 
 numerous temples, the temple of Victory, the Erectheum, with 
 the temple of Minerva Polias and the Pandrosium, and the 
 splendid Parthenon, all these were adorned with the most costly 
 statues and works of art, and enriched with gold and silver 
 vessels. And besides these great works, how many were the 
 perpetual small expenses, of which we have scarcely any notion, 
 that occurred in an ancient state: for example, the building of 
 altars, which were always erected for certain festivals***'. 
 
 Here we may also mention the construction of roads, not 
 only as regards the paving of streets in Athens, but the forma- 
 tion of the roads to the harbours, of the sacred road to Eleusis 
 and perhaps to Delphi as far as the boundary, since it is asserted 
 
 *'^ De Vectig. 4, 44. Scylax men- 
 tions four fortresses, Eleusis, Ana- 
 phlystus, Sunium, and Rhamuus. 
 
 ^'* Thucyd. viii. 4. 
 
 2 * Xenoph. Hell. i. 2, 1 ; cf. de Vec- 
 tig. ut sup. 
 
 =*'« Thucyd. ii. 18. 
 
 4, 2 ; Diod. xiv. 
 
 *'^ Xenoph. Hell. ii. 
 32; Nep. Thrasyb. 2. 
 
 ^•^ Demosth. de Coron. p. 238. 
 
 ^'^ Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 2, 10. 
 
 ^^° Ileliodorus ap. Ilarpocrat. and 
 Suidas, and Photius in TrponvXaia. 
 
 "' Plutarch, in vit. Demosth. 27.
 
 CH. X.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 
 
 203 
 
 that the Athenians first opened the road to this place. I grant 
 that the Romans and Carthaginians expended more money upon 
 the construction of roads than the Greeks; but roads were 
 formed which were much travelled over, and intended in parti- 
 cular for sacred processions; these were not merely constructed 
 with an uneven pavement, but were made firm and smooth with 
 small stones taken out of the quarries*^". 
 
 For the superintendence of all these labours there were 
 some regular officers, and some appointed only for certain 
 periods. Over the wharfs and the ships that lay in them, the 
 inspectors of the wharfs {iTri/jLeXrjTal t6)v vewplwv) were placed**^; 
 for the repairs of the walls certain commissioners {TeLj(oTTOLol) 
 were named, the most distinguished amongst all the directors 
 of the public works (eTna-raral tmv hrjfjboaiwv epycovY^*, who, 
 like the builders of the triremes, were elected one from each 
 tribe'". All other buildings were under the superintendence 
 of a manager of public works: it was in this capacity that Peri- 
 cles, and subsequently Lycurgus, undertook so many works of 
 architecture"^ In the building of the temple of Minerva 
 Polias, we likewise find directors {eirccrTaTal) who had a clerk^''^ 
 and probably every temple had directors of this kind, who 
 together with the priests and sacrificers {lepoiroiol) composed a 
 college or board''*^. Similar authorities were appointed for the 
 care of the roads and of the supply of water [ohoiroLol, eTrcararal 
 Tcov vBaTcovY^^, The astynomi composed the street police, five 
 
 **^ iKvpov as well as Xarvir-q is what 
 breaks off in the hewing of stone, and 
 sometimes even signifies mortar. From 
 this is derived o-KvpcoTrj 686s, of which 
 kind there was one at Cyi'ene for pro- 
 cessions (Pindar Pyth. v. 90 sqq.), con- 
 sequently it is not a paved road, but 
 made in the same manner as ours, only 
 with greater care. 2KvpaiTr) 6865 is 
 however interpreted by Xt^dcrrptoroy, 
 and therefore it seems to me probable 
 that this word does not always mean a 
 paved road, but one formed with stones. 
 
 *^' Sigon. R. A. iv. 3, where he also 
 speaks of the builders of the walls. 
 
 ^^^ ^sch. c. Ctesiph. p. 400. Pollux 
 viii. 114, improperly includes them 
 among the vTrrjperai, as well as the 
 sacrificers {Uponoiol) and Bodnae. 
 
 '^-^' ^schin. ut sup. p. 422, 425. 
 
 ^■'^ Plutarch Pericl. (cf. Diod. xii. 
 39), and the Life of Lycurgus in the 
 Lives of the Ten Orators. 
 
 '^7 See the inscription cited in note 
 232. 
 
 '■^'^^ At least so the passage in In- 
 script. 76, § 7, may be interpreted. 
 
 '-^'■^^ Sigon. ut sup. p. 17G, vol. i. of 
 hisAvorks; Petit Leg. Att. v. 1, 3. 
 Concerning the odonoiol see more par-
 
 204 
 
 THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 
 
 [BK. II. 
 
 in the city and as many in the Piraeus : among other duties, 
 they had to attend to the cleansing of the streets, and had on 
 that account the superintendence of the scavengers (/cott/do- 
 
 All works of building undertaken by the pubHc were by the 
 proper authorities let to contractors [epjoXa^ot], as was the 
 case at Rome; this is particularly mentioned of the repairs of 
 the temples and public buildings*'^, and an inquiry was made 
 from time to time, probably at the change of office, how far the 
 building had proceeded, and what was still remaining to be 
 done. An inscription, in which the unfinished parts of the 
 building of the temple of Minerva Polias in the archonship of 
 Diodes (Olymp. 92, 4, b.c. 409), are recited, has been preserved 
 to our days*^^ 
 
 The amount of money expended upon works of building was 
 necessarily quite undefined, and must obviously have depended 
 upon the quantity of disposable revenue and the necessity of 
 the projected work. Demosthenes received nearly 10 talents 
 for the repairs of the walls^^^; but it is uncertain whether, as he 
 was appointed only for the tribe Pandionis, he received all the 
 money, or whether it was divided between him and his nine 
 colleagues; the last supposition is rendered more probable 
 from the circumstance of several treasurers being mentioned: 
 that the expenses of building were defrayed by the state and 
 not by the tribes, as might appear from another passage of 
 ^schines, is sufficiently manifest from the fact that the money 
 was furnished by the administration. Probably the commis- 
 sioner of each tribe had a particular part of the walls to repair, 
 and Demosthenes received the sum just mentioned for the 
 expense of his share; this being insufficient, he added, accord- 
 ing to the testimony of a contemporary decree, and of another 
 which was made subsequently, 3 talents of his own money, 
 
 ticularly ^schin. c. Ctesiph. p. 419, 
 and the comic poet ap. Plutarch. Pra^c. 
 Poht. 15. The Kpr]vo(PvXaK€s men- 
 tioned by Sigonius probably were not 
 public ofiicei"S (see the note of the 
 editor upon the passage quoted). 
 
 ^^^ Aristot. ap. Harpocrat. in v. 
 darvpofioi. 
 
 =^3' Petit. Leg. Att. i. 2, 7- 
 
 2^^ Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. No. 160. 
 
 '■"'^ JEsch. c. Ctesiph. p. 415, cf. p. 
 425.
 
 en. X. 
 
 THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 
 
 205 
 
 in addition to which he caused two trenches to be drawn round 
 the Pireeus at his own expense^^\ Conon, the son of Timo- 
 theus, was obhged to repair a part of the walls at a cost of 10 
 talents. In general the surplus of the revenue only was applied 
 to building, unless necessity compelled the infraction of this 
 rule : thus in an ancient decree it is ordered that whatever 
 should remain over and above the money assigned for the pay- 
 ment of the public debts should be appHed to the repairs of the 
 wharfs and walls"\ In the time of Pericles this overplus was 
 extraordinarily great, on account of the large sums produced by 
 the tributes, and out of this fund the public treasure was formed ; 
 thus he was able, as Plutarch^^^ says, to build temples which 
 cost even 1000 talents, and in fact he used 3700 talents out of 
 the treasury for works of architecture and for the Potidsean 
 war"^, besides what he may have added from the current reve- 
 nue. Before his time, not only Pisistratus, but Themistocles 
 and Cimon had spent much money in building; after these, 
 Conon deserves to be mentioned, as the restorer of the walls, 
 and Lycurgus, who completed the many works that had been 
 left unfinished, the wharfs, the arsenal, and the theatre of 
 Bacchus; it was he who laid the foundation of the Panathenaic 
 stadium, the gymnasium, odeum, and lyceum, embellished 
 the city with several other works, and moreover furnished many 
 decorations for processions, and for the temple of Minerva, 
 golden statues of Victory, and gold and silver ornaments for 100 
 canephoree"^ 
 
 But upon the whole the public buildings of this age were 
 inconsiderable when compared with those of earlier times, while 
 the splendour of private buildings had increased. " In ancient 
 
 '^* Decret. ap. Demos tli. de Cor. p. 
 266, aud decrees after the Lives of the 
 Ten Orators. In iEsch. c. Ctesiph. p. 
 405, only 100 minas are mentioned, but 
 evidently from a confusion with the 
 sum which he contributed as manager 
 of the theorica (de Coron. p. 266) ; he 
 is followed by the author of the Lives 
 of the Ten Orators (p. 263, ed. Tu- 
 
 bing.). Concerning Ccnon see Nepos 
 Timoth. 4. 
 
 ^" Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. ^6, § 9. 
 
 ^« Pericl. 12. 
 
 2^7 Thuc. ii. 13. 
 
 ^° See the passages in Meursius 
 Fort. Att. p. 58 of the 4to edition, 
 where nothing is omitted but the ori- 
 ginal source, viz. the third decree after 
 the Lives of the Ten Omtors.
 
 206 
 
 THE PUBLIC BUILDINGS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 days/^ says Demosthenes*^", " everything that belonged to the 
 state was costly and splendid, and no individual distinguished him- 
 self from the multitude; and the proof of it is, that if any of you 
 know the houses of Themistocles and Miltiades, and the famous 
 men of that time, he will see that they are not more magnifi- 
 cent than those of other people; but the buildings and construc- 
 tions of the state were of such grandeur that it is not in the 
 power of succeeding generations to surpass them — the Propy- 
 leea, the wharfs, the porticoes, the Piraeus, and the other works 
 with which you see the city adorned. But now all who are 
 concerned in the management of public affairs have such a 
 superfluity of riches, that some have built private houses more 
 magnificent than many public edifices ; and some of them have 
 purchased more land than all of you w^ho are sitting in the court 
 are together possessed of; but your public buildings and works, 
 it is digraceful to tell how scanty and contemptible they are. 
 What indeed can be said of your works ? what of the parapets 
 which we throw up ? of the roads which we construct, and the 
 fountains and the trifles at which we labour ?" Thus speaks 
 the ardent enthusiast for the happiness and fame of his 
 country; his speeches of admonition might with a few alter- 
 ations be adapted to the present age, in which such vast sums 
 have been squandered away without producing anything great 
 or durable. 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 
 The Police. The Scythian Bowmen. 
 
 It is evident that the police could not possess that distinct and 
 important character among the Greeks, which it has in the 
 states of modern Europe, as from their republican government, 
 judicial decisions were always preferred to the operations of 
 police. It is indeed wholly impossible for such an institution 
 
 239 C.Ari8toc.p.689, 11-24. Olyntli. 
 iii. p. 35, 36, which two passages I have 
 combined. See tlie spurious speech 
 
 iT(pl (rvvTd^eu>s, from p. 174, 17, to p. 
 175, 12.
 
 CH. XI.] 
 
 THE POLICE. 
 
 207 
 
 as a secret police to exist as a separate establishment in a 
 democracy: but a strict and vigilant inspection was produced 
 by the privilege which the citizens possessed of coming forward 
 as accusers in all things which affected the public interest, 
 though this right was not exercised without malignity, envy, 
 and calumny. There existed a system of watching and 
 espionage, which was not less oppressive and formidable than 
 the worst institutions of modern despots; although it had the 
 double advantage over these, that no person could be con- 
 demned without a public trial, and that it cost the state 
 nothing. 
 
 The only kind of police which existed as a distinct institu- 
 tion in ancient times, was that to which was entrusted the per- 
 formance of certain needful services, such as the street-police, 
 which was in the charge of the astynomi, together with that of 
 the market and traders, which latter did not cause any expense: 
 and finally, some institution must have been indispensable as 
 well in respect to the aliens, as to the maintenance of order and 
 security in the city, particularly in the public assembly. In all 
 the Grecian states, notwithstanding their hospitality, foreigners 
 were considered as enemies, and for that reason they were at 
 Athens under the jurisdiction of the archon polemarchus, as at 
 Rome under that of the praetor peregrinus : it is not improbable 
 that the foreign police as well as some establishment for grant- 
 ing passports was under his direction, of which a slight indica- 
 tion occurs in a passage of Aristophanes^*". For the mainte- 
 nance of security and order there was a city-guard composed of 
 public slaves {hrj/xoo-LOLy*^: these persons, although they were 
 of low rank, enjoyed a certain consideration, as the state em- 
 ployed them in the capacity of baihfFs. Such public slaves 
 were sometimes also appointed for the trade-police^"^; and sub- 
 ordinate places, such as heralds and checking-clerks, together 
 with other offices in the assembly and courts of justice, were 
 filled by persons of the same description. The public slaves 
 
 **» Av. 1209, and Schol. ad 1214. 
 The name is cr^payif, cru/x/SoXoi/. 
 
 ^*^ Concerning these see Hai'pocrat. 
 Suid. Etym. Pollux ix. 10, and Hera- 
 
 sterhuis' note, also Maussac ad Harpo- 
 ci-at. in V. brj^xoaios, Lex. Seg. p. 234. 
 
 *^^ Boeckh. Corp. Inscript. 123, § 5 
 sqq.
 
 208 
 
 THE SCYTHIAN BOWMEN. 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 who composed the city-guard must be looked upon as a body- 
 guard of the Athenian people; which thus resembled Poly- 
 crates the t}Tant of Samos, who kept 1000 bowmen about his 
 own person*". They are generally called bowmen (rofoTat), or 
 from the native country of the majority, Scythians, also Speu- 
 sinians; they lived under tents in the market-place, and after- 
 wards upon the Areopagus***. Among their number there were 
 also many thracians and other barbarians. Their officers had 
 the name of Toxarchs {ro^apxoiY^^ Their number increased 
 progressively: in the first instance 300 were purchased soon 
 after the battle of Salamis^*^; subsequently it rose, according to 
 the Scholiast to the Acharneans of Aristophanes and Suidas, to 
 1000, according to Andocides and ^schines, to 1200**^ It is 
 evident that these troops might, if necessary, be used in the 
 
 2^3 Herod, iii. 39, 45. 
 
 ^^■^ Pollux viii. 132, and his com- 
 mentators, Aristoph. Lysistrat. 437; 
 Acham. 54; Schneider ad Xenoph. 
 :Mem. Socrat. iii. G; Lex. Seg. p. 234; 
 Photius in To^orai. 
 
 ^*^ Corp. Inscript. No. 80. 
 
 2^® iEsch. nepl Tvapanpea^. p. 335. 
 
 2^' iEschin. ut sup. p. 336, x'^'oi^s" 
 5e Kal diaKoaiovs imreas KareaTTjO-apev 
 Kol To^oras €T(povs TocrovTovs. Hiero- 
 nymus Wolf asks whether 300 or 600 
 are meant, as he makes irepovs roaov- 
 Tovs refer to the 300 mentioned in p. 
 335, which were first bought: it is 
 clear to me that erepot roaovToi used 
 in this manner can only refer to the 
 number which immediately precedes, 
 and therefore in this place only to 
 ;j(iXiovs Kal diaKocrlovs, and that here 
 the whole number of the bowmen is 
 meant, including those that were first 
 bought, most of whom might besides 
 have died and their vacancies been 
 filled up. It is undeniably true as 
 Hier. Wolf observes, and as Viger has 
 said after him, that once as mayiy is 
 often said, when the preceding num- 
 ber is reckoned, and tlie same number 
 is added. But unquestionably, taken 
 
 in its original and strict sense, it means 
 ! jvLst as many, as ef^os roiovroSf another 
 ! person of the same kind, as in ^sch. c. 
 Ctesiph. p. 488, ck niKonovvrjaov fiev 
 TrXeiovas rj 5tcr;(tXtou? onXiTas, e£ 'A/fap- 
 1 vavias de irepovs toctovtovs . That 
 , this is the force of it in the present 
 '. passage is shown more particularly by 
 Andocides de Pace, p. 93, x'-^'-^^^ ''^ 
 Kal diaKOcriovs Imreas, Kal To^oras roaov- 
 Tovs erepovs KaT€(TTr}o-ap.€v, where the 
 preceding number fixes the meaning 
 of TOCTOVTOVS. This also agrees the 
 best with Suidas and the Scholiast. 
 There were 1200 horsemen at Athens, 
 but Xenophon only speaks of 1000. 
 The same account is given by Suidas 
 and the Scholiast in reference to 
 ^schines. The only thing that can 
 be remarkable is the word erepovs, 
 since bowmen were not cavalry ; this 
 however is e\ndently according to tlie 
 same idiom, by which Xenophon says, 
 Tovi oTrKiTas Kai tovs (iKkovs vmreas. 
 Moreover the rest of the narration 
 shows that the author is not speaking 
 here of bo>vmen in general but of the 
 slaves, since the first .300 are distinctly 
 said to have been bought.
 
 en. XI.] THE SCYTHIAN BOWMEN. 209 
 
 field, although the Athenians had also free bowmen, of whom I 
 shall presently speak. 
 
 The expense which this regiment occasioned may be nearly 
 ascertained. As it was necessary for them to be strong, able- 
 bodied men, upon whom dependence could be placed, the 
 purchase-money cannot be fixed at less than 3 or 4 minas 
 apiece: and as the whole number would have required renewal 
 about every 30 or 40 years, exclusively of any increased 
 number of casualties which might have been produced by war, 
 30 at least must have been purchased annually, which would 
 have caused an expense of from 1^ to 2 talents. Their pay 
 doubtless amounted to 3 oboli a day^^% making altogether 
 about 36 talents a year. 
 
 Chapter XII. 
 Celebration of Festivals and Sacrifices, 
 
 The celebration of festivals produced in the early times of 
 the Athenian republic, a profuseness of expenditure in no way 
 inferior to that of the courts of luxurious princes : this republi- 
 can system however possessed several advantages over the latter 
 sort of useless expenditure. For, in the first place, all the 
 citizens partook in these solemnities, and not a select few; in 
 the second place, they were founded upon the duties of religion; 
 and again, the public games or contests, which had a powerful 
 influence in forming the national mind, awakened and improved 
 the taste and spirit of the people. To expend large sums of 
 money on the fine arts, which appeared in the highest perfec- 
 tion at the sacred festivals, upon costly but lasting ornaments 
 for the temples, upon choruses and musical entertainments, and 
 upon a theatre, which was so perfect that it excelled equally in 
 tragedy and comedy, were considered as acts of a liberal and 
 noble mind. And while the Athenians were led by their reli- 
 gious obligations to these costly practices, the Spartans were 
 satisfied to manifest their piety by offering small sacrifices to 
 
 From the traces in Inscript. No. 80.
 
 210 CELEBRATION OF FESTIVALS [bK. II. 
 
 the gods. That the person who provides the sacrificial feast 
 should receive a share of the offering, appears both natural and 
 reasonable; but when the principal revenues of the state were 
 wasted upon public banquets, and the sacrifices were maintained 
 at the public expense, not so much for the purposes of religion, 
 as for the support of the poor^*% the policy of the Athenians 
 was alike unjust and inexpedient, inasmuch as the continuance 
 of it without oppressing the allies was impossible, and the state, 
 being deprived of the means of self-defence in a most frivolous 
 and unpardonable manner, was led on to certain destruction. 
 The Athenians not only had twice as many festivals as other 
 Grecian states**", but everything was considered secondary to 
 them. "The Panathensea, the Dionysia,^^ says Demosthenes**', 
 " are always celebrated at the proper time, festivals on which 
 you expend more money than on any naval enterprise, and for 
 which you make such preparations as were never heard of else- 
 where; but when you send out a fleet it always arrives too 
 late.^^ Even Plutarch, by nature of an admiring and laudatory 
 turn of mind, w^ho with his beautiful style and amiable dis- 
 position has misled the understandings of many readers by 
 engaging their feelings, in his Essay upon the Glory of 
 Athens"*, perceives this weak point. For after having enume- 
 rated the various splendour of the tragedies, he thus proceeds. 
 " Gazing upon this the Lacedaemonian justly remarked that the 
 Athenians erred greatly in making serious matter of trifles, that 
 is, in expending upon the theatre sums sufficient for the equip- 
 ment of large fleets, and for the maintenance of great armies. 
 For if it were calculated what sum each play cost the Athe- 
 nians, it would be found that they had spent more treasure 
 upon Bacchses, and Phoenissses, and CEdipusses, and Anti- 
 gones, and the woes of Medea and Electra, than upon wars 
 undertaken for empire and for freedom against the Barbarians. ^^ 
 With the exception of the theoricon, the most considerable 
 expenses of the festivals were those for sacrifices, plays, and 
 processions. In many festivals all these three were combined. 
 
 2*« Cf. Xenopli. de Rep. Ath. 2, 9. I "' Philipp. i. p. 50, 3. 
 "■^^ Xenoph. ibid. 3, 8. I ^" Cap. fi.
 
 en. X 
 
 ••] 
 
 AND SACRIFICES. 
 
 811 
 
 as, for instance, at the great Dionysia^ and such festivals must 
 therefore have been extremely expensive"". The sacrifices 
 were of very different kinds ; a number of small offerings, con- 
 sisting either of young pigs, sheep, cocks, &c., or of cakes, and 
 fruits, were sacrificed to some god or object of worship: of this 
 description were the sacrifices performed before every public 
 assembly and every sitting of the senate and the courts of jus- 
 tice; and, in the second place, more expensive sacrifices, which 
 had been in use from early times. The ancient and most sacred 
 offerings were called paternal sacrifices {irdrptoi, Ovaiat), and 
 were opposed to those which were made at the more recent, or, 
 as they were called, the additional festivals {eiriOeTov eoprat). 
 In the bad times which ensued, the former were at most but 
 sparingly solemnized, or were sometimes entirely discontinued: 
 at the celebration of the latter great banquets were given, for 
 which perhaps three hundred oxen were slaughtered at the 
 public cost, and the paternal sacrifices were paid for out of the 
 rents of the sacred estates, or rather they were furnished by a 
 contractor for a certain sum, who was indemnified out of these 
 rents"^ It is easy to judge of the immense number of these 
 great sacrifices, from the fact, that the money received for skins 
 
 253 ^jj account of the costliness of j 
 the Dionysia, especially on account of 
 the sacrifices, is given in the second 
 book of Pseud-Aristot. CEcon. sec. G, 
 where it has been thought that Athens 
 was meant. It is however by no 
 means certain that it relates to that 
 town, as may be seen from Schneider's 
 note. It seems to me most probable 
 that it should be referred to Antissa, 
 as the man is called 'Ai/ncro-aios, who 
 is mentioned as the originator of the 
 proposal there cited. 
 
 ^^* Isocrat. Areopag. 11. Oi»S' 6i 
 TTore ^€V do^eiep avrois, rpiaKocriovs 
 ^ovs eirefXTTOv' oTTore be rvxoiev, ras 
 narpiovs Ovalai e^eXinoV ov8e ras pev 
 eniderovs eopras (cf. Harpocrat. in h. 
 v.), ais etrriacrls ris Trpocreir], p.(ya\o- 
 Trpencos rjyoVy iv fie rots' ayicoTarois Tav 
 UpSiv ano fJLi(T6(0fxdTa)v fSvov. That 
 
 OTTO piaOcopcLTCiv mcaus eK Tcov repevt- 
 Kcov TTpoaodcoVf we learn from Harpo- 
 cration in this phi-ase. That the 
 sacrifices were let to contractors is 
 shewn by the last words of this 
 article : ov yap kut fixre^eiav Z6vov to. 
 lepe^a, dWa piadovpevoi, and more dis- 
 tinctly in Lex. Seg. p. 207, of which I 
 only transcribe the end : cSos yap ^v 
 Tois ^ovXopevois pia-6ova6ai ras OvalaSt 
 Ka\ reXoy rjv Toiv Bvcriatv TVOiXovpevov rai 
 jBovXopeva: an incorrect expression, 
 for how could it be called a WXof, when 
 a contractor undertook any thing at 
 the expense of the state ? Concern- 
 ing the neglect of the Trdrpioi Bvcriai^ 
 see also Lysias c. Nicomach. in the 
 passage quoted below, and concerning 
 the public banquets in the temples 
 Petit i. 2, 1. 
 
 P 2
 
 212 
 
 CELEBRATION OF FESTIVALS 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 (hepixaTLKov) in Olymp. 111.3 (b.c. 334), amounted to 5148f 
 drachmas for only seven months^. Thus live hundred young 
 kids were sacrificed to Diana Agrotera alone at the festival for 
 the battle of Marathon"*: but the frequent sacrifices of oxen 
 were particularly designed to allure the people, on which 
 account Demosthenes"^ connects this donation of oxen with 
 the theoricon. A hecatomb alone cost upon an average a 
 talent"^; and many other expenses were necessarily connected 
 with these solemnities. The law of Solon upon the sacred 
 tablets [Kuppei^] had fixed the amount of the sacrifices and of 
 other solemnities; a single one was rated at 3 talents. But this 
 in the age of Lysias appeared very inconsiderable: a secretary 
 named Nicomachus, who was employed to transcribe the laws, 
 fixed it upon his own authority at 9 talents, and moreover at 
 a moment when the state had from poverty suflfered the walls 
 and docks to fall out of repair, and was unable to pay 3 
 talents to the Boeotians, as an indemnity for the reprisals made 
 against them: by which means the state lost 12 talents in 
 two years, and was incapable of performing the paternal sacri- 
 fices^*^. Demosthenes, when he was manager of the theoricon, 
 contributed 100 minas to the sacrifices, which he paid out of 
 that fund^*^; a proof that, though for the most part well filled, 
 it did not satisfy the people. 
 
 Besides the sacrifices furnished by the state {BrjfiOTeXrj lepa), 
 there were many others provided by particular corporations and 
 societies, such, for instance, as those furnished by the demi 
 (hrjiioTLKa lepa) and by the societies of orgeones {opyeco- 
 rt/tfa)""; not to mention the feasting of the tribes, of which I 
 
 •= See Boeckh.Corp.Inscript. No. 157. 
 
 '■^" See the passages in my Preface 
 to the Catalogue of the Lectures in 
 tlie University of Berlin, Summer, 
 1816, p. 4. 
 
 "« Olynth. p. 37, 6. These were 
 presents from the public coflfei-s. Those 
 referred to in the second Prytaneia 
 of Inscript. No. 147. are quite dif- 
 ferent. 
 
 "7 Book i. ch. 14. 
 
 2-^ Lysias c. Nicomach. p. 850 — SCO, 
 
 which passage has not been entirely 
 understood by the commentators. 
 
 ^^^ Decret. ap. Demosth. de Coron. 
 p. 266, 23. Lives of the Ten Orators, 
 p. 263, where the words dircdcoKe Se Kal 
 6eo)po7s (a singular expression) fxvpias 
 refer to this circumstance. 
 
 ^^^ Lex. Seg. p. 240;. Hesychius and 
 Harpocration in v. dTjfioreXTJ lepa. 
 Some of these expressions occurred in 
 the Laws of Solon, as e. g. the drfp-orfXij 
 lepii. See yEsch. c. Timarch. p. 47,
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 AND SACRIFICES. 
 
 213 
 
 will speak in a subsequent part of this work*. The entertain- 
 ments at the festivals were either musical or gymnastic, both 
 being attended with considerable expense. The choruses, both 
 in and out of the plays, their teaching, maintenance, and dresses, 
 the cost of the musicians and actors, together with the decora- 
 tions, machinery, and dresses, and in the gymnastic games, the 
 maintenance of the combatants of all kinds, and the preparation 
 of everything which belonged to their exercises and contests, 
 required a considerable outlay of money : and although this was 
 in part provided by direct Liturgies, the Choregia and Gymna- 
 siarchy, it all came at last from the same source ; and it makes 
 no essential difference whether the state raised the money and 
 gave entertainments for it, or whether private individuals pro- 
 vided the games instead of paying the money in the shape of a 
 tax. To these must be added the prizes awarded to the success- 
 ful competitor, of which some had no great value, while others 
 were costly, and were given either in money (in the ayoyves 
 apyvptrai), crowns, or tripods, which either the state or who- 
 ever defrayed the costs of the festival provided, or the conqueror 
 himself furnished at his own expense"'. There occurs in an 
 inscription^^^ a golden crown of victory weighing 85 drachmas, 
 which must at the least have cost 1000 or 1200 drachmas of 
 silver. At the games of Neptune in the Pireeus, the first Cyclic 
 chorus that gained the victory, received, according to a regula- 
 tion of Lycurgus, at the lowest a reward of 10 minas, the second 
 
 p. 176, c. Ctesiph. p. 566. These words 
 also occur in the speech against Nesera 
 (p. 1374, 2, p. 1374, 4,) in the Formula 
 elcrievai els to. drj/jLoriKT] iepa, which 
 induced Reiske, in the Index to De- 
 mosthenes, and Buttmann ad Mid. 
 p. 125, to think that the temple was 
 meant : but elauvai els to. lepa evi- 
 dently refers in particular to the ad- 
 mission to the sacrifices, although it 
 also includes permission to enter the 
 temples in which the sacrifices were 
 held. To these passages all the inter- 
 pretations of the grammarians refer, 
 and pcrliups to the words of the Dodo- 
 na'an oracle excellently emended by 
 
 Buttmann ad Demosth. c. !Mid. p. 531, 
 24. Buttmann also quotes from Pol- 
 lux the ^TjfxoTeXels ioprai, from which 
 these sacrifices were bought. Thyatir. 
 Inscript. in Spon's Travels, vol. iii. 
 parti, p. 110, Tas drjfioTeXus Ovaias 
 Koi iopras dcjiOovcos Koi dwTrepKpiTcos 
 eTTiTeXeo-avra. Thucydides (ii. 15,) has 
 iopTTjv S77/iorfX^, Dio Cassius (xLiii. 
 25,) and Herodotus (vi. 57,) OvcriTjv 
 dT]p.0T€Xrj. 
 
 ^ B. iii. ch. 23. 
 
 '^^'- Lysias pro Aristoph. bonis, and 
 Inscript. 158, § 5. 
 
 ^'^^ No. 150, § 15.
 
 214 
 
 CELEBRATION OF FESTIVALS [bK. II. 
 
 8, and the third 6'"'; and even Solon granted to the Athe- 
 nians who gained the prize in foreign sacred games, (^. e, in the 
 four great contests,) rewards of a certain sum of money, which 
 for that age were not inconsiderable, to the conqueror at the 
 Olympic contests 500 drachmas, at the Isthmian 100, and to 
 the others in proportion"\ 
 
 Lastly, something may be said upon the splendour of the 
 Athenian irofxirai, or sacred processions. These indeed yielded 
 in nothing to the theatrical representations: no expense was 
 spared for them, and even the cavalry was partly maintained 
 in time of peace for their sake. Another expense connected 
 , with this subject were the public burials {Srj/jLoatac racfyal)^ 
 which indeed only occurred in time of war. Again, the greater 
 and less theorias, or sacred embassies, were of frequent occur- 
 rence, which were sent, after each of the four great Grecian 
 games, to Delos and to other sacred places, for the purposes of 
 festivals, and united in themselves sacrifices and processions. 
 One part of the expense was borne by the architheorus as a 
 liturgy, another part by the state : thus the Delphian theori, 
 according to an ancient law, received money for their journey 
 and all their other expenses ; and thus Aristophanes mentions 
 the wages of a theorus to Paros of so small an amount as 2 
 oboli*"; thus also the Delian architheorus received a talent 
 from the public purse*^^ The theori were obliged to appear 
 "with a splendour and dignity suitable to the character of their 
 nation ; they themselves, wearing splendid crowns, drove into 
 the city upon crowned chariots, which were often expensively 
 painted, gilt, and hung with carpets^^^ When Nicias went as 
 architheorus to Delos, he built a bridge from Rhenea to Delos, 
 for his entry, 4 stadia in length*^^ The passage of the theori 
 
 •^3 Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 252. at all suit the context; in the latter 
 
 ^* Petit Leg. Att. i. 1, 29, 30. 
 ^' Concerning the former see An- 
 drotion ap. Schol. Aristoph. Av. 1545 
 
 case a soldier would have been called 
 in joke a theonis, which is very im- 
 probable. 
 
 (comp. above book ii. ch. G); concern- ^^^ Inscript. l5o, § 5. 
 ing the latter see Aristoph. Vesp. ^"^ Hesych. in v. decopiKos and his 
 1183, where neither the entrance- 
 money into the theatre, nor the pay of 
 the soldiers, can be meant, as the 
 Scholiast tliinks. The first does not 
 
 commentators, and Plutarch. Nic. 3. 
 
 268 i>i^tarch. ut sup. See Taylor ad 
 Marm. Sandw. p. 18.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 AND SACRIFICES. 
 
 215 
 
 and choruses from Athens to Delos, cost on a later occasion 
 7000 drachmas^^^^ and the quadriennial Delian festival, which 
 was celebrated entirely at the expense of this theoria, cost, 
 according to the accounts now extant, inclusively of this latter 
 expense, but with the exclusion of many other items which have 
 been lost, 4 talents 43 drachmas, although they were not paid 
 out of the funds of the state, but from those of the temple of 
 Delos. From all that has been said, it is easy to conceive that 
 the state expended much money upon the celebration of fes- 
 tivals ; and at times it even became necessary to resort to the 
 public treasure for money to defray those expenses. Thus in 
 Olymp. 92, 3, 5 talents and 1000 drachmas were paid out of 
 the treasure for the athlothetae, at the celebration of the great 
 Panathensea, and 5114 drachmas to the sacrificers for the heca- 
 tomb, and an Olympiad earlier the athlothetse received at the 
 same festival 255 Cyzicenic staters (7140 drachmas)^'"*. A 
 large part of the other payments in Olymp. 92, 3 (410 B.C.), 
 appear, according to an account of the money disbursed from 
 the public treasure, of which the destination is not specified, to 
 have been also for festivals*^^ 
 
 For the administration and superintendence of all religious 
 solemnities certain unpaid authorities were appointed, who 
 ranked among the principal public officers. Of this description 
 are the managers of the mysteries, and of the Dionysia (eVt/i-e- 
 \7)Tal Tcov /jLvo-rrjplcov, rcov Alovvctlcov) : to particular archons 
 certain sacrifices also belonged^'^, as well as to the generals*'^, 
 together with the collectors of the people (avWoyets tov 
 ByfjLovY^*, and all sacred rites at Delos were managed by the 
 amphictyons ; but the most numerous officers were the yearly 
 and monthly sacrificers, the former of whom were ten in num- 
 ber ; and again there were sacrificers for the revered goddesses 
 
 2f« Inscnpt. 158, § 5. 
 
 270 Inscript. 147, 2d Pry tan. In- 
 scnpt. 144; Pryt. 3, Item 3. 
 
 ^7' Barth^lemy Mem. de I'Acad. des 
 Inscriptions, torn. xLviii. p. 378, calcu- 
 lates the money supplied out of the 
 public treasure for the festivals, as 
 
 given in the Choiseul Inscription, upon 
 perfectly false suppositions ; for which 
 reason I have made no use of his com- 
 putation. (Ibid. No. 147.) 
 
 272 Sigon. R. A. iv. 7. 
 
 2?=* Inscript. 157, § 2, 3. 
 
 2'^ Inscript. 157, § 2.
 
 216 
 
 FESTIVALS AND SACRIFICES. 
 
 [bk. II, 
 
 or the Eumenides {lepoirotol Kar iviavTov, iiri/JL'qvtoL, lepoiroioi 
 ral^ crefivals OealsiY'^, For the games there were tlie athlo- 
 thetae, who had the particular care of the great Panathensea 
 (though probably with the exception of the sacrifices) *'% as also 
 the agonothetae, ^c. Lastly^ the /Socovac, or purchasers of oxen^ 
 were considered among the highest officers ; Demosthenes ranks 
 them with the sacrificers, and Libanius with the sitonee, gene- 
 rals, and ambassadors: they were elected by the public assembly, 
 and provided the cattle and animals which were slaughtered at 
 the sacrifices and feasts*''; a proof how important to the people 
 these institutions were, which suited equally their appetite and 
 their principles of religion, and by which we are forcibly reminded 
 of the roast beef of old England. 
 
 Chapter XIII. 
 Donations to the People. 
 
 The public donations, or distributions among the people (htavo- 
 fial, ^taS6aeL9), were of frequent occurrence. To these belong 
 the distributions of corn, which have been mentioned before"% 
 
 *'' Hesychius in v. iepoTroioi, and 
 his commentators, ■who quote Photius 
 and other grammarians, Pollux, viii. 
 107, and his commentators. Lex. Seg. 
 p.265,they also occur particularly often 
 in Inscript. 157, i. P- 250. See also 
 Bai-thelemy ut sup. p. 342. The iepo- 
 Troioi Tcov aep-vav Oeatv^ quoted by 
 Photius, are taken from Demosth. in 
 :Mid. p. 652, 6. Whether they, as 
 Creuzer represents them (SjTnbolik, 
 vol. iv. p. 518), were properly priests 
 for sacrifices, might appear imcertain, 
 if Demosthenes did not show that they 
 at least performed the commencement 
 of the sacrifice, or the immolation of 
 tlie victim (to Kardp^aadai tcov Upcov). 
 The grammarians also consider the 
 tepoTTotoi as having actually performed 
 the sacrifice. Aristotle Polit. vi. 8, 
 expresses himself too generally to 
 allow a safe conclusion to be drawn. 
 That they had however certain duties 
 
 of administration to perform is evident 
 from Inscript. Nos. 147 and 158. That 
 the aepval deal are the Eumenides 
 is remarked by Ulpian, Photius, and 
 Harpocration, in v. a envoi $ealj and 
 Lex. Seg. p. 303. 
 
 2"« See Inscript. No. 147, Pryt. 2, 
 
 although the grammarians assert, (see 
 
 Barthe'lemy and Photius, and Lex. 
 
 Seg.) that the sacrificers had nothing 
 
 to do at the great Panathenaea. 
 
 i 277 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 570, 7, and 
 
 ] there Ulpian. Liban. Declam. viii. 
 
 ; Harpocrat. Suid. in v. ^oa>vT)Sj Lex, 
 
 j Seg. p. 219, Harpocration: on Xa/x- 
 
 TTpos rjv 6 ^oa)V7]s Kal al fxeyiarai apxai 
 
 I enl rovTto ex^eiporovovm-o. Pollux viii. 
 
 114, incorrectly includes them among 
 
 , the inferior offices, or offices of service 
 
 I {vTnjpeaiai). They occur frequently 
 
 I in Inscript. 157- 
 
 ^'' Booki. ch. 15.
 
 CH. XIII.] DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. 2lJ 
 
 the cleruchige, and the revenues from the mines, which before 
 the time of Themistocles were divided among the citizens ; and 
 lastly, the money of the theorica, for the introduction of which 
 Pericles is chargeable. For this statesman, finding himself 
 unable by reason of the scantiness of his fortune to vie with 
 other public leaders and demagogues in liberality, thought of 
 supplying his private incapacity (according to the testimony of 
 Aristotle, at the suggestion of Demonides of CEa), by a distribu- 
 tion of the public revenue, and bribed the multitude partly with 
 the theorica, partly with the payment of the dicasts, and sala- 
 ries of other descriptions*'^: while he at the same time main- 
 tained himself in popular favour by processions, feastings, and 
 other solemnities. 
 
 The admirers of the Lacedaemonian customs, who, like Plato 
 and his master, formed a correct judgment in a moral point of 
 view, perceived that Pericles had made his countrymen covetous 
 and indolent, loquacious and effeminate, extravagant, vicious, 
 and unruly, by maintaining them at the public expense with 
 donatives, salaries, and cleruchiee'^^*', and by flattering their sen- 
 suality and love of enjoyment with sumptuous festivals. Peri- 
 cles indeed had too acute a mind to overlook the consequences 
 of his own measures ; but he thought that there was no other 
 means of maintaining his own and the people^s sovereignty in 
 Greece, than by supporting the populace in this manner ; he 
 was aware that with him the power of Athens would cease, and 
 he endeavoured to preserve it as long as was possible; but upon 
 the whole his contempt for the people was as great as his libe- 
 rality towards them. In the mean time the people, so long as 
 Pericles Uved, were neither wanting in activity nor public spirit, 
 which tended to make these measures more harmless ; and as 
 long as neither injustice abroad, nor negligence in the national 
 enterprises, nor disorder in the state, resulted from them, it 
 might even appear just that the citizens should enjoy the fruit 
 of their exertions and valour. Besides which Pericles could not 
 suspect that, twenty Olympiads after his death, the multitude 
 would rather consume the public revenues in feasting, than 
 
 ^'5 Plutaich. Pericl. », cf. 11. '^^'^ Plat. Gorg. p. 515 E. Plutaicli. Peiicl. 9.
 
 218 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. [bK. II. 
 
 equip an armament in defence of their freedom, a corruption 
 which was first produced by the avaricious and treacherous 
 demagogues of later days, who flattered every whim of the 
 twenty-thousand-headed hydra. These considerations might 
 then appear to palhate the conduct of Pericles. But he must 
 have been aware that the unavoidable result of his measures 
 was to increase the oppression of the allies, the dominion of the 
 multitude, and the injustice towards the opulent citizens. While 
 Pericles himself only raised the tribute by a small amount, his 
 successors were forced to augment it to a far greater extent, in 
 order to keep up his profuse expenditure. The surplus of the 
 tributes was brought by talents at the Dionysia into the orchestra 
 to be distributed : here the aUies were shown in what light their 
 property was viewed'^^'. The oligarchical party was well aware 
 that the abolition of these payments would be a severe blow to 
 the democracy ; and accordingly, during the government of the 
 Five Thousand (Olymp. 92, 1,412 B.C.), which was only of 
 very short duration, no superior office received any salary ^^*. 
 Aristotle^^^ has indeed already remarked, that the different kinds 
 of salaries, for example, the wages of the public assembly, are 
 dangerous to the chief persons in the state, for that they occa- 
 sion the imposition of property-taxes, confiscations of joroperty, 
 and bribery of justice. Not only was it the practice to adjudge 
 property to the state, in order to increase the revenue^^*, but the 
 demagogues publicly declared in law-suits, that if judgment was 
 not given in some certain manner, the salaries could no longer 
 be paid to the people^^^ ; and therefore the wealthy, in order to 
 prevent every jealousy, made voluntary- donations of their posses- 
 sions^^^ It sometimes happened that the proceeds of confiscated 
 property were distributed among the citizens without authority; 
 and even Lycurgus divided in this manner 160 talents, which 
 the property of Diphilus had produced. Thus they were not 
 satisfied that by these distributions the state was deprived of its 
 most powerful resources for useful and advantageous objects. 
 
 *«> Isocrat. (TVfiiJiax. 29. i ^* Lys. c. Nicom. p. 8G1. 
 
 '"-^^ Thucyd. viii. 1)7. ^" Lys. c. Epicrat. init. 
 
 2** Polit. vi. 5. I
 
 CH. XIII.] DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. 219 
 
 but those who profited by these measures encouraged in the 
 people a desire to obtain the property of others, and widened 
 the breach between the rich and poor, which in the states of 
 antiquity was an incessant and highly dangerous evil. Aristotle 
 justly compares these ii^stitutions to the perforated vessel of the 
 Danaides, as the Athenians were perpetually receiving taxes, 
 and then paying them away, and were then compelled to raise 
 fresh supplies*^; but the moral corruption which they caused 
 was a far more pernicious consequence; the Athenians were 
 themselves, to make use of an illustration of Plato's, the 
 vessels of the Danaides, which were continually receiving the 
 gratification of their desires, without ever being completely 
 satisfied. 
 
 The distribution of the theorica, which, as we have seen, 
 produced such fatal consequences to the Athenians, had its 
 origin in the entrance-money to the theatre. The entrance 
 having been at first free, and crowds and tumults having arisen 
 from the concourse of many persons, of whom some had no 
 right to enter, it was to be expected that in a theatre con- 
 structed of wood, which was the only one that Athens then 
 possessed, the scaffolding would break; and this accident in 
 fact took place; to avoid which evil it was determined to sell 
 the seats for 2 oboli; but in order that the poor might not be 
 excluded, the entrance-money was given them, on the delivery 
 of which each person received his seat*^". Persons of high rank 
 doubtless at first disdained this as well as other donations ^^^; 
 though in the age of Demosthenes they received the theo- 
 ricon^^^. It is possible that the entrance-money for the theatre 
 
 •286 jierald. Aniraadv. in Salmas. 
 Observat. ad I. A. et R. vi. 3, 13. 
 
 '^ [Aristot. Polit. vi. 5, "Onov 8' elal 
 npoaoboi, fiT] TTOieiv o vvv oi Sjy/xaycoyoi 
 TToiovfXL' TO. yap TrepLovra vep^ovai. Aafi- 
 
 wliere, as in Photius, there is a mix- 
 ture of the articles occurring in the 
 other grammarians. The account given 
 in Lex. Seg. (Sik. ovo/j..) p. 1«19, 29, 
 does not deserve to be mentioned. 
 
 ftdvov(Tt be ap.a kul naXiv beovrai t5)v \ ^^^ See Herald. Animadv. in Salmas. 
 avToiv' 6 rerpTjiievos yap ecTTL ttlOos rj Obser. ?id I. A. et R. vi. 3, 11. 
 ToiavTT] ^oTjdeia rots aTTopois.] ^^^ Philipp. iv. p. 141, 18, Avhich ora- 
 
 ^^^ Liban. Argnm. ad Demosth. ' tion, as Yalckenaer and Wolf have 
 Olynth. 1 ; Schol. Lucian. Timon. 49. justly remarked, is not the production 
 Suidas in the first article of OiwpiKov, of Demosthenes, but is composed of 
 and Etymol. in v. OecoptKou apyvpiov, different passages of this orator, and is
 
 220 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. [bK. II. 
 
 was introduced before the theoricon was first paid by the state; 
 it may be fairly supposed that, the citizens having for a time 
 defrayed it at their own expense, the state undertook to pay 
 for the poor ; and the introduction of the entrance-money may 
 be fixed without improbability as early as the 70th Olympiad 
 (B.C. 500), at which time the scaffolding fell in suddenly, when 
 Pratinas, and probably also ^schylus, were representing in the 
 theatre'"'. But the payment of the theoricon out of the public 
 money was first introduced by Pericles'''; and when Harpo- 
 cration calls Agyrrhius the author of the theoricon in the 
 extended sense of a distribution of money, he refers to an 
 increase of it made at a later period, of which I shall speak pre- 
 sently"'. This distribution of the theoricon filled the theatre*'^ 
 We may observ^e, that the entrance-money was paid to the 
 lessee of the theatre (deaTp(ovr,<^^ dearpoircoXrjs, apxt'Te/cTcovY^*, 
 who was bound to keep the theatre in repair, and who paid 
 something to the state for rent, as we see in the case of the 
 theatre at the Piraeus. Ulpian, a writer on whom very little 
 dependence can be placed, affirms that 1 obolus was given to 
 the lessee of the theatre, or, as he calls him, to the architecton, 
 and that the citizens received the other for their support ; this 
 statement is however without foundation, for, according to 
 Demosthenes, the regular entrance-money was 2 oboli"^; 
 although it is so far true, that a separate payment of theorica 
 was made for the banquet of the citizens *"^ It might also be 
 supposed that, as Demosthenes reckons the entrance-money 
 among the smaller revenues of the state, the payment was 
 
 written in the style of a sophist. The 
 defence of the theoricon in 'particular, 
 which occurs in p. 141, is in direct 
 contradiction with Demosthenes. 
 ^^'^ Yid. Gra?c. Tragoed. Princip. p. 
 
 2^3 Plutarch de Sanit. Tuend. p. 373, 
 vol. i. ed. Hutt. 
 
 29^ Ulpian. ad Demosth. Olynth. 1 ; 
 cf. Casaub. ad Theoph. Char. 11. 
 
 235 De Corona, p. 234, 23. 
 
 38, and particularly Hennann de Choro j '^® Harpocrat. in v. decopiKop (from 
 Eumenidum jEschyli Diss. ii. p. viii. j Philinus), from which the second ar- 
 xiv. tide of decopiKo. in Suidas, and the 
 
 ''^^' Ulpian. ad Demosth. Olynth. 1 ; ; third in Photius, is transcribed. As 
 Plutarch. Pericl. 9. this is frequently the case, I shall not 
 
 ^'^ Petit iv. 10, 9, imjustly charges ( always quote Suidas and Photius, 
 the grammarian with confounding this where they have nothing new. 
 with the pay of the assembly.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. 
 
 221 
 
 received on the public account, and not for the lessee ; but 
 even though the tenant received it, it might have been enumer- 
 ated among the national profits, inasmuch as he paid a rent to 
 the slate; so that this example from Demosthenes, who only 
 speaks in general terms, and without any great precision, proves 
 nothing in contradiction to my opinion. 
 
 The privilege of receiving the theorica was obtained through 
 registration in the book of the citizens {Xrj^capxi'fcbv ypafi/jba- 
 retovY^''; the distribution was made both individually and by 
 tribes*^*, absentees receiving nothing"^; and it took place in 
 the assembly'"'', which was sometimes held in the theatre, 
 particularly when the business related to the celebration of 
 the Dionysia^"'. The application of the theorica was soon 
 extended, and money was distributed on other occasions than 
 at the theatre^°^, though always at the celebration of some 
 festival; and as either a play or procession was invariably con- 
 nected with it, the name still continued applicable. Under the 
 head of theorica were also comprised the sums expended upon 
 sacrifices and other solemnities^*'^ Not only at the Panathe- 
 naea^"*, but at all the great festivals {lepo/jLrjvLacy^^, theorica were 
 distributed. In the Choiseul Inscription we find that in Olymp. 
 92, 3 (b.c. 410), from the public treasure alone (probably how- 
 ever on condition of repayment) in the first seven prytaneias 16 
 talents 4787 drachmas were paid to the hellenotamise, under 
 the name of diobelia, which formed a part of the theorica. The 
 citizens were thus to be enabled to celebrate the festival with 
 greater luxury; and from this altered destination of the money 
 there has arisen an uncertainty whence the theoricon took its 
 name; and Ammonius, in direct contradiction to Csecilius, 
 denies that it had reference to spectacles {deaty^^. From this 
 
 '^' Demosth. c. Leochar. p. 1091 sq. 
 
 ^^8 Herald, ut sup. vi. 3, 10, also 
 Lucian Timon. 49. 
 
 S.99 Hyperides ap. Harpocrat. \\t sup. 
 
 300 ^sch. c. Ctesiph. p. 642. 
 
 30' Lex. ap. Demosth. c. ^lid. p. 
 517. Compare Isocrat. avfifiaX' 29. 
 
 ^0- Libanius ut sup. 
 
 303 Hesych. in v. deaptKa ;^pi7/iara, 
 6ea>pLKov dpyvpLov, and 6€(opo\, and his 
 commentators. See above, chap. 7- 
 
 30^ Hesych. in v. OecopiKu ;^pi7/xara. 
 Dem. 0. Leochar. ut sup. 
 
 305 Ulpian. ad Demosth. Oljnith. iii. 
 
 306 Ammonius in v. decopos, where 
 he falsely derives it from decov ^puv :
 
 222 DOXATIOXS TO THE PEOPLE. [bK. II. 
 
 uncertainty the question suggests itself^ whetlier the rate of the 
 theoricon for the separate festivals was not raised when its 
 objects were multipUed^ and whether the difference in the state- 
 ments of ancient writers may not be thus explained. The 
 grammarians speak in general of 2 oboli''^; the inscription above 
 referred to mentions the diobelia, as also Aristotle and the 
 Lexicon Rhetoricum''^ In an oration falsely indeed attributed 
 to Demosthenes, but not on that account undeserving of 
 credit^" % the theoricon, for the distribution of which a nominal 
 assembly was held, is estimated at 2 oboli. On the other hand, 
 Philochorus, as quoted by Harpocration, states, that " the 
 theoricon was originally a drachma for the theatre, whence in 
 after times it received its name,^^ and the grammarians mention 
 the same amount^'"; Lucian^^' speaks of the drachma and the 
 3 oboli, where from the context the former can only be referred 
 to the theoricon, and the latter to the pay of the assembly or of 
 the dicasts; and in the spurious Prooemia to the Public Speeches 
 of Demosthenes'''^ it is said, "with the drachma, and the chus 
 (of wine probably), and the 4 oboli (which latter I confess I 
 cannot explain), the orators prolong the life of the people, as 
 physicians do of the dying,^^ The difficulty appears to vanish 
 if we admit that the theoricon was very variable, which seems 
 to be pointed at by Harpocration; nor will I deny that this was 
 the case: since however 2 oboli are mentioned both in ancient and 
 recent times, it does not appear to have been raised by increasing 
 the regular rate; the change was probably effected by doubling or 
 trebling the same 2 oboli for festivals which lasted several days, 
 in such a manner that for a festival of three days a drachma was 
 
 Bia TO iv Tols eoprals els rovs deovs j ovs Kadrjfjievos 6 drjuos efiKrBocjjopei. 
 
 cvo-e^e'iv koX eTndveiv (as Valckenaer ^'^^ Uepl crvvrd^. -p. 1G9, 1. 
 
 corrects for iiriQeiv) koI evcjipaiveadat. ^^^ Hesych. and Suid. in v. dpaxp-f] 
 
 '^^"^ Ulinan, Libanius, Suidas, in the i xaXa^wfra, Zenob. iii. 27- 
 first article, Etymol. Pliotius in the j ^^' Deniosth. Eulog. 36, where J. M. 
 first article, Schol.Aristopli.Vcsp. 1183. [ Gessner thinks that the drachma is the 
 
 ^"^ Aristot. Polit, ii. 5 (ii. 4, 11, ed. pay of the orators, which however is 
 Schneid.), who calls it dioi^oXia, al- ' too small a sum for the regular stipend, 
 though he speaks of it with another ■ to be meant here. He should have 
 view. Schneider has not examined ' rather instanced the pay of the senators 
 the subject with sufficient accuracy, i ^'^ P. 1459, 27. 
 Lex. Seg. p. 2:'>7, f^tw/yeXta- o/3oXot dvn, ]
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. 
 
 223 
 
 given, and for one of two days 4 oboli, to which the above-cited 
 passage of the pseudo-Demosthenes may be referred. Hesychius, 
 Suidas, and Zenobius, indeed, assert, that in the archonship of 
 Diophantus the theoricon amounted to a drachma; but this is 
 not contrary to my supposition. Diophantus was archon in 
 Olymp. 96, 2 (b.c. 395), according to Petit's correct remark, 
 against which it is needless to object that the nation could not 
 at that time have given so high a theoricon, as it had not yet 
 recovered from its impoverished state; for it was precisely at 
 this moment that the condition of Athens began to ameliorate; 
 and with the democratic constitution which then existed, it 
 would undoubtedly have been the first object to restore the 
 theoricon: and this probably was in fact the case; so that for 
 the great festivals of three days a diobelia was paid three times. 
 From a passage of Harpocration^^^ rather obscurely expressed, 
 it may be inferred that its renewal was effected by Agyrrhius, 
 who flourished at this period, and who, as will be presently 
 shown, tripled the pay of the assembly about the same time. 
 Moreover it may be observed, that in the age which followed 
 the anarchy, the price of an ordinary place in the theatre 
 remained at 2 oboli^''*; the price of the best places at the 
 representation of comedies was at the highest no more than a 
 drachma^ ^^ 
 
 ^'^ In V. BeaptKci : BecopLKo. rjv riva 
 iv Kotvw ;^pj7/xara otto tc5i/ r^y TroXfoos' 
 7rp6crob(ov crvvayofxeva' ravra be Tvpore- 
 pOV p€U els TUS TOV TTokipov )(p€ias 
 e<pv\dTT€TO Kal eKaXeiro "STpaTio^TiKa, 
 vcrrepov Se KaTerideTO e'ls re rcis drjpoaias 
 KaracTKevas Kal diavopas, av npcoTos 
 TJp^aTO 'AyvppLos 6 8T]fxaya)y6s. Pliotius 
 has the same article, only he omits tlie 
 most important part, the mention of 
 Agyrrhius. 
 
 ^'* Demosth. pro Corona, p. 234, 
 where he says if it had not been ordered 
 that the architecton was to assign a 
 place to Philip's ambassadors, they 
 must have sat ev rolv bvoiv oftoKoiv, 
 which should not be taken with Hier. 
 Wolf for bvoiv 6(36\oiv, for in that case 
 
 what woiild be the use of tlie preposi- 
 tion and the article ? Reiske cor- 
 rectly refers it to a particular place ; 
 it means however a common, as op- 
 posed to a good, seat ; such for instance 
 as the place of those who had the pri- 
 vilege of proedria (cf. iEschin. c. Cte- 
 siph. p. 4G6), which the ambassadors 
 occupied: what Ulpian (p. 281, ed. 
 Bekker.), or rather the collection of 
 scholia composed of various kinds of 
 notes, says in this place about a trio- 
 bolon and an obolus, is mere absurdity. 
 ^^^ Plat. Apol. Socrat. p. 26 E. 
 Suidas also and Pliotius (in the second 
 article) in v. decopiKa, and Schol. Lu- 
 cian. ut sup. assert that a drachma was 
 the highest sum which was given for a
 
 224 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. [bK. II. 
 
 If we reckon that 18^000 people received the theoricon — 
 and the number cannot have been well less — the diobelia 
 for one day amounted to a talent; and since it was without 
 doubt paid on twenty-five or thirty days in the course of a 
 year, the lowest rate at which we can estimate the annual 
 expense of it, is from 25 to 30 talents. They were not however 
 satisfied with allowing it to remain at this point, but, as I have 
 before remarked, they squandered away as theorica all the 
 money destined for the uses of war. It was by this means that 
 the Athenians delivered themselves to the power of Macedon. 
 "With the death of Epaminondas," says Justin"^ who pro- 
 bably avails himself of an idea of Theopompus, " perished also 
 the virtue of the Athenians. For after the excitement which 
 had been produced by the emulation existing between the Athe- 
 nians and Epaminondas had ceased, they resigned themselves 
 to indolence and inactivity, and squandered away on festivals 
 and shows the public revenue which formerly had been used for 
 the equipment of fleets and armies. Then were the taxes, with 
 which soldiers and sailors used to be maintained, distributed 
 among the inhabitants of the city. Thus was Philip able to 
 gain the ascendancy .^^ AVhat in Pericles indeed originated from 
 no motives of patriotism, was employed by profligate demagogues 
 to work upon a depraved multitude; and w^e may here remark 
 that nothing can be a more striking proof how destructive the 
 immorality of the governors is to the welfare of the governed. 
 For is it not the fact that the chief promoters of the theoricon 
 were men distinguished for their effeminacy, immorality, and 
 general depravity ? Agyrrhius, who by his profuse administra- 
 tion of the public revenue obtained so great popularity, that 
 after the death of Thrasybulus (Olymp. 97, b.c. 389) he was 
 appointed to succeed him as generaP'^, was notorious for his 
 effeminacy, farmed the taxes like an usurer, and was in prison 
 
 place; but to suppose that a lower sum ^'® \i. 9. He says at the end, Dj- 
 was never given, as they assume, with vidi coeptum est, wliich is not entirely 
 tlie exception of Photius, is absurd, correct. 
 
 since it would contradict what occurs I ^'^ Xenoph, Hell. iv. 8, 31 ; Diod* 
 before. I xiv. 99.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. 
 
 225 
 
 many years for embezzlement of public money^'". Eubulus of 
 Anaphlystus, by his distribution of the theorica^ arrived at the 
 highest pitch of popular favour^ '% and after his death great 
 honours were decreed him (as had been done to Lycurgus and 
 Demosthenes), which Hyperides spoke of in his oration Trepl 
 Twv Ev^ovXov BcopeMv; but he was strongly suspected of being 
 in the pay of Philip, and was actively instrumental to the 
 downfal of his country. The severe but impartial Theopompus 
 gave his character with perfect justice, " that he was a celebrated 
 demagogue, active and indefatigable in his vocation, but that 
 during his administration and by his distributions of money, 
 Athens sunk to the lowest state of inactivity and indolence, 
 exceeding even Tarentum in extravagance and debauchery^^"/' 
 Lastly, what shall we say of Demades, who promised each 
 Athenian 50 drachmas for the Choeis in order to hinder the 
 equipment of a fleet against Alexander for the support of the 
 common safety of Greece^*' ; and carried his effrontery to such 
 a pitch as to call these distributions the cement of the demo- 
 cracy^*^? Even ^schines^*^ did not go so far as this, for he at 
 least declared himself hostile to the distribution of the revenue; 
 
 ^^^ Concerning him see Harpocra- 
 tion in v. 'Ayvpptos, and there Valesius 
 and Suidas, also Demosth. c. Timo- 
 crat. p. 742, 16, and Andocid. deMyst. 
 p. 65, who ironically calls him top 
 Kokov KayaObv, and the passages col- 
 lected by Meursins, Lect. Att. vi. 4. 
 
 ^'^ See book ii.c.l and 7- Concerning 
 the theorica which he distributed, see 
 more particularly Philinus ap. Harpo- 
 crat. and Photius in v. Oeapim. 
 
 3*® Theopompus in the tenth book 
 of the History of Philip had treated 
 of the Athenian demagogues, and par- 
 ticularly of Eubulus. Some account 
 from that source is given by Harpo- 
 cration in v. Ev^ovXos, and more by 
 Athen. iv. p. 166 E, according to whom 
 he had called him aa-coTos. But the 
 passage of Theopompus quoted as a 
 proof refers to the Athenian people 
 and not to Eubulus: koI too-ovtov 
 
 acTCOTia Kol TrXeove^ia dievrjvoxe rov 
 Brjfiov Tov TapavTivcov, oa-ov 6 p-ev nepi 
 Tcis i(TTLa<jei9 eix^ p.6vov aKpaTTjSy 6 Se 
 tSv 'ABrjvaicov Koi ras TTpoaodovs Kara- 
 piaBo(f>opav diareTeXeKcv. Casaubon 
 perceived this, but Schweighseuser 
 confuses it all again, although the 
 passage of jEschines (c. Ctesiph. p. 
 300), which he had already quoted 
 upon the word KaTap.icr6o(f)op€7p might 
 have taught him that the people is 
 meant. Theopompus however had 
 e-vddently censured Eubulus severely, 
 and compared him to his disadvantage 
 with Callistratus, the son of Callicrates, 
 whose luxurious life he indeed blamed, 
 but appears to have praised his poli- 
 tical conduct. 
 
 ^^^ See book ii. ch. 6. 
 
 3-^ Plutarch. Qu. Plat. x. 4. 
 
 3^ iEschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 642.
 
 226 DONATIONS TO THE PEOPLE. [bK. II. 
 
 although his professions and his real opinions probably disa- 
 greed. What however was the public and private life of De- 
 mades ? Though a man of such splendid qualities of mind that 
 an ancient said of him, that he was above the state, while he 
 could only call Demosthenes worthy of the state, he yet 
 became openly a traitor to his country, indulging only his own 
 appetites, and his principles were as loose as his wit was 
 unscrupulous. It is vain to urge in extenuation of his public 
 conduct that a fragment only of the vessel of the state was left 
 to his charge, which was scarce worth preser^dng from ship- 
 wTCck; he himself was, as Plutarch happily expresses it, the 
 shipwreck of the state^^*. How disgracefully he yielded himself 
 to the will of Antipater; how did he delight in every unlawful 
 practice, and in dissolute opulence, fragrant with perfumes and 
 walking in a costly chlamys ! He lived in such a manner that 
 Antipater could never supply him with money sufficient for his 
 purposes, and aptly said of him when he grew old, ^that like a 
 dressed ox upon the altar, nothing remained of him but belly 
 and tongue^". His profligate life hardly allows us to bestow 
 upon his mournful death the compassion which common huma- 
 nity would dictate. 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 Pay of the Members of the Public Assembly, and of the Senate, 
 
 The salaries at Athens were of various kinds, but the most 
 important were the wages of the assembly, the senate, and the 
 dicasts. 
 
 The nature of democracy requires that all public affairs 
 should be determined upon by the whole people in an assembly^ 
 and that the business and decrees be prepared beforehand by a 
 select body, which should have the management of them, and 
 execute the resolutions of the popular assembly; and unless 
 
 '2^ Plutarch. Plioc. 1, where he calls | there is however no other word by 
 him the vavayiov ttjs noXeois, which , which it can be translated into our 
 does not however signify shipwreck, | langxiage. 
 but a fragment of a vessel wrecked ; | ^^^ Pint. Plioc. 20, 2fi, 30.
 
 CH. XIV.] PAY OF THE PUBLIC ASSEMBLY. ' 22? 
 
 the governing power is to fall into the hands of the mob, the 
 people should receive no pecuniary compensation for their 
 share in the government, an expense which it is impossible to 
 defray by revenues justly raised; it is a condition requisite for 
 good government, that all who wish to partake in the ruling 
 power should support themselves upon their own property. 
 Athens was not, however, the only state in which the people 
 were paid for governing; a similar system of salaries had been 
 introduced at Rhodes by the demagogues^^^ As to the wages 
 of the dicasts, it is right that some compensation should be 
 allowed for the performance of judicial duties, and it has been 
 at all times customary; oligarchies, indeed, were enabled to 
 compel the rich by the threat of punishment to execute these 
 duties, whereas in democracies the poor were paid for their 
 labour^^^ But from the number of judges in a democratical 
 court of justice, this practice could not exist without the 
 expenses being defrayed by a tax, which it was impossible to 
 raise without oppression. And if Athens, like other states, had 
 only decided her own law-suits, it would not have been neces- 
 sary to pay the dicasts; the citizens would have remained at 
 their business, active and industrious. But to the great injury 
 of the allied states, Athens, in order to insure her own power, 
 usurped the jurisdiction over them, and the people were well 
 pleased that the custom-duties became by these means more 
 productive, that the judicial fees were multiplied, and that the 
 rent of houses and slaves was increased^^^ Under these cir- 
 cumstances the number of causes was so much augmented that 
 there were more to decide in Athens than in the whole of 
 Greece; and the law-suits, particularly as the festivals produced 
 so large a number of days on which no business was done, were 
 extremely protracted, unless indeed they were accelerated by 
 bribery^*', which was carried on at Athens, as well as at Rome, 
 in an open and systematic manner. Nearly the third part of 
 the citizens sat as judges every day; hence that passion for 
 
 '^ Aristot. Polit. v. 5. 
 
 327 Aristot. Polit. iv. 9 and 14. 
 
 32« Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 3, Aris- 
 toph. Av. 1430, 1465. 
 3^^ Xenoph. ut sup. 3, 2. 
 
 Q 2
 
 228 
 
 PAY OF THE MEMBERS OF 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 judging necessarily arose^ which Aristophanes describes in the 
 Wasps, and the citizens were thus not only made averse to 
 every profitable and useful employment, but were rendered 
 sophistical and litigious, and the whole town became full of 
 pettifoggers and chicaners, who were without any real know- 
 ledge of law or justice, and on that account only the more rash 
 and thoughtless. According to the expression of the comic 
 poet, they sat like sheep, muffled up in their cloaks, and with 
 their judicial staff, for 3 oboli a day, thinking indeed that 
 they managed the affairs of the state, while they were them- 
 selves the tools of the party-leaders. 
 
 The wages of the assembly {/jLcadbs eKKKr^cnaa-TLKos) the 
 sovereign people paid to itself. The honour of inventing this 
 salary is contended for between Callistratus and Agyrrhius, 
 and fortunately both claimants can be satisfied. Pericles, as 
 far as we know, had no share in it, and it may be asserted with 
 sufficient probability that this payment had not been intro- 
 duced in the early part, at least, of his administration. " When 
 the noble Myronides ruled,^' observes Aristophanes^^", with 
 reference to the wages of the ecclesiasts, " no one administered 
 the affairs of the state for money .^^ Now Myronides was an 
 early contemporary of Pericles^^'; after the time then of this 
 Myronides, and consequently long after the beginning of the 
 influence of Pericles, the payment of the ecclesiasts was intro- 
 duced, which at first amounted to 1 obolus, and afterwards 
 to 3. Callistratus Parnytes first introduced the obolus as the 
 pay of the ecclesiasts^^^, and this was a considerable time before 
 the Ecclesiazusae of Aristophanes, which was acted in Olymp. 
 96, 4 (b.c. 393); but at what particular period we are ignorant, 
 since who this Callistratus was is wholly unknown. The most 
 celebrated of the persons of this name is Callistratus, the son of 
 
 ^'^ Eccles. 302. 
 
 331 Myronides was general in the 
 80tli Olympiad (b.c. 400-57), Thiicyd. 
 i. 105, 108, iv. 95; Diod. xi. 97, 81 ; 
 cf. Plutarch. Pericl. 10. The Myro- 
 nides in Deniosth. c. Timocrat. p. 7-12, 
 25, is a different person. 
 
 ^^* Append. Vatic. Proverb, iii. 35, 
 '0/3oX6j/ evpe Tlapvvrrjs. That Petit 
 should suppose (iii. 1, 3,) that the ec- 
 clesiasts here mentioned miglit be the 
 orators, is quite natural, as he always 
 hits upon the most improbable expla- 
 nation.
 
 CH. XIV.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC ASSEMBLY 
 
 229 
 
 Callicrates, of Aphidna, the near relation of Agyrrhius'^% a 
 famous orator and general in the 100th and 101st Olympiads^^* 
 (B.C. 380-73), censured for his private life by Theopompus, 
 but praised for his zeal in the public service^"; he is said to 
 have excited Demosthenes to the study of eloquence by the 
 famous law-suit concerning Oropus^^% and having been at first 
 acquitted, was afterwards condemned to death in Olymp. 104, 3 
 (B.C. 362); he lived in Macedonia, chiefly at Methone, and was 
 the "founder of Datum^^^, and is doubtless the person to whom 
 the improvement in the system of custom- duties in Macedonia 
 is ascribed^-^^; finally, after his return from exile he was put to 
 death. This person, however, lived at too late a period to have 
 been the introducer of the obolus; and still less can we suppose 
 it to have been the Callistratus, who wasarchon in Olymp. 106, 
 2 (B.C. 355). Not then to mention less] noted persons of this 
 name, it is more probable that Callistratus, the son of Empedus, 
 is meant, who in Olymp. 91, 4 (b.c. 413), perished as com- 
 mander of cavalry in the Sicilian expedition^^^; or perhaps Cal- 
 listratus of Marathon, who in Olymp. 92, 3 (b.c. 410), was 
 treasurer of the goddess^***, and probably is the same person 
 as the knight of the tribe Leontis (to which Marathon be- 
 longed), who was killed during the anarchy by the party in the 
 Piraeus^'''. The increase in the wages of the ecclesiasts to 3 
 oboli evidently took place but a short time before the Ecclesia- 
 zusae of Aristophanes, perhaps in Olymp. 96, 3 (394 b.c.)^*S 
 
 ^^^ Concerning him see Demosth. 
 pro Corona, p. 301, 18, c. Timocrat. p. 
 742, 23, de Fals. Leg. p. 436, 13, 
 Orat. c. Neser. p. 1353, 19, and p. 
 1359, 18, c. Timoth. p. 1187, 7, p. 1188, 
 10, p. 1198, 10. The latter speech, 
 together Avith that against Neaera, is 
 probably not the work of Demosthe- 
 nes, according to the suspicion of the 
 ancients ap. Harpocrat. in v. kgko- 
 
 '''^* See book iii. ch. 18. He also 
 occurs in Xenophou's Hellenics. 
 
 335 Ap. Athen. iv. p. 166 E. 
 
 ^^« Cf. Ruhnken. Hist. Crit. Orat. 
 p. 140, vol. viii. of Reibke's Orators. 
 
 337 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1220, 1221; 
 Scylax p. 27, Isocrat. crvn^ax- 9, comp. 
 Niebuhr, Transactions of the Berlin 
 Academy for 1804—1811, p. 93, 94. 
 
 3^« Pseud-Aristot. CEcon. 2, 22. 
 This he did in his exile, not for Athe- 
 nians, as Schneider appears to think, 
 but for the Macedonians. 
 
 3^^ Pausan. vii. 16. In the Lives of 
 the Ten Orators (Demosth. ad init.) 
 this one is strangely confounded with 
 the celebrated Aphidnean. 
 
 3^0 Inscript. No. 147, at the begin- 
 ning. 
 
 3*1 Xenoph. HeU. ii. 4, 18. 
 
 3^^ Aristoph. Eccl. 302, 380, 392,
 
 230 
 
 PAY OF THE MEMBERS OF 
 
 [bk. 
 
 when Agyrrhius re-established the theoricon; to him also the 
 Scholiast upon Aristophanes^'^ ascribes the first introduction of 
 the wages of ecclesiasts; from which it is evident, as Petit 
 remarked^", that he was the person who increased them. 
 
 The number of the Athenian citizens cannot be taken on 
 an average, as has been before shown, at more than 20,000; it 
 is absurd then to suppose that there were assemblies of 30,000 
 persons. But of these 20,000 many were absent in the coun- 
 try on military service, or upon mercantile business; or even if 
 they were in the city, they did not attend the assembly; so that, 
 particular cases being excepted, it is impossible to imagine that 
 the assembly ever contained a very large number. But after 
 the introduction of the 3 oboli, there was a more numerous 
 attendance of the poor citizens, " Formerly when the eccle- 
 siasts only received 1 obolus,^^ says Aristophanes in the 
 Ecclesiazusae, " the people sat talking; now that they receive 
 3 oboli they crowd in numbers^^^; and jostle against one 
 another for this small sum^^^" But the wealthy usually were 
 
 543. This increased pay also occurs 
 in the Plutus, vs. 329, which passage 
 is therefore from the second edition 
 produced in Olymp. 97, 4 (b.c. 389)j 
 the date of the first is Olymp. 92, 4 
 (B.C. 409). The triobolon in the 
 ccclesia is also mentioned by the 
 Schol. Aristoph. Tlut. 171. 
 
 3^3 Eccl. 102. 
 
 "^^ Leg. Att. iii. 1, 3. The Scholi- 
 ast of Aristophanes (Plut. 329, 330,) 
 speaks of the pay being raised to 3 
 oboli, which was said to have been 
 done by Cleon, but we must avoid 
 understanding this of the wages of the 
 ecclesiasts, which arc there confound- 
 ed with the pay of the dicasts, although 
 the words are ambiguous ; it refers to 
 the wages of the dicasts. Both have 
 'been frequently confounded with one 
 another by both ancient and modern 
 interpretei*s ; for instance, by Span- 
 heim upon Aristophanes, and by the 
 Scholiiist to the same poet. The 
 author of the note to the 8Glst verse 
 
 of the Clouds even explains the 
 o^oXos TjXiaaTLKos as the pay of the 
 ecclesiasts, which passage is not to be 
 be corrected, but the mistake is solely 
 to be attributed to the ignorance of 
 the writer. I may also mention that 
 I have intentionally omitted Pollux 
 viii. 11 3, as his words are too indefinite 
 to allow us to infer from them witli 
 Mein-sius (Lect. Att. v. 12, vi. 4,) that 
 the wages of the ecclesiasts ever were 
 an obolus; it is even preferable to refer 
 the three words that occur there, 
 rpico/SoXoj/, dioo^oXov, and o/3oX6$-, all 
 to the pay of the dicasts. 
 
 3^5 Aristoph. Eccl. 302 sqq. Com- 
 pare with this the opinion of Aristotle, 
 (Polit. iv. 15,) that where the nation is 
 Avealthy or the ecclesiasts receive pay, 
 the people being unoccupied fre- 
 quently assemble and decide every- 
 thing, without the senate having any 
 great influence. 
 
 ^*^ Aristoph. Plut. 329.
 
 CH. XIV.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC ASSEMBLY. 
 
 231 
 
 glad to stay away from the public assemblies, so that Aristotle^''^ 
 recommended that a fine should be imposed upon them if they 
 did not attend, and to give wages to the poor alone, in order to 
 produce a salutary mixture of both classes ; the rich therefore 
 always composed the minority. It is probable that we should 
 not err much if we took an assembly of the people at about 
 8000^; we know that in certain cases, particularly for the 
 ratification of a decree relating to an individual {privilegium) , 
 such as ostracism or the admission of a fresh citizen, 6000 
 votes were requisite^^^, in order to secure a large majority; in 
 general then not many more than 6000 could have been pre- 
 sent. If we suppose 8000, the wages of an assembly taken at 
 3 oboli amount to about 4000 drachmas. Now there wxre 
 forty regular assemblies in a year; the extraordinary meetings 
 (which were numerously attended) at very disturbed seasons 
 exceeded the number of the regular^' ^; but upon an average 
 not more than ten can be fairly assumed, one being reckoned 
 to each prytaneia. Consequently the wages of the assembly 
 cannot be estimated at more than 30 or 35 talents, and thus 
 it is not true that they fell more heavily on the public than 
 the wages of the dicasts^^". The money was paid to each per- 
 son as he entered the assembly by the thesmothetee^^', which 
 
 3^7 Polit. iv. 14 ; cf. iv. fi. 
 
 e The author says in the Addenda 
 that " the number of citizens attend- 
 ing the ecclesia is estimated too high. 
 According to the oligarchs in Thucy- 
 dides viii. 72, there never was an as- 
 sembly of 5000 to deliberate on the 
 most important questions: kuItoi ov 
 TTWTroTC ^ABrjvaiovs dia ras arpaTeias kol 
 TT]v vTvepopiov dcrxo^iav es ovbev 7rpdyp.a 
 ovTco p-^yo. eXdelv ^ovKevcrovras, iv <a 
 nevraKiaxi-X^ovs ^vvikQciv. According 
 to this passage then it must be assumed 
 that the 6000 votes, which was the 
 number prescribed for certain ques- 
 tions, was not the number of those who 
 voted for the particular subject in de- 
 bate, but only of the citizens who voted 
 both ways on the question, which in- 
 deed is expressly stated to have been 
 
 the case with regard to the Ostracism, 
 although when I wrote the passage in 
 the text it appeared to me improbable. 
 The accurate investigation of this point 
 must however be deferred to some 
 other occasion." 
 
 3^« Petit. Leg. Att. ii. 1, 8 ; ii. 3, 10; 
 Sigon. R. A. ii. 4. The remarks that 
 Petit has made in different places (ii. 
 1,8; iii. 1,3; iii. 3, ad fin.) concern- 
 ing this majority of the votes, which 
 was not by any means necessary for all 
 decrees, arise from mere misapprehen- 
 sion and delusion. 
 
 3^9 ^sch. de Fals. Leg. p. 251. 
 
 ^^^ As Meiners says in his Geschichte 
 des Urspr lings, Fortgangs, und V erf alls 
 der Wissenschaften, vol.ii. p. 150. 
 
 2^1 Aristoph. Eccl. 290.
 
 232 
 
 PAY OF THE SENATE. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 officers received it from the treasurer of the administration: 
 those who came too late received nothing^^^. 
 
 Of nearly equal amount were the wages of the Senate of 
 Five Hundred (fnaOos ffovXevTiKos). These amounted to a 
 drachma for each day on which the senate assembled'*^. Now 
 the senate sat mostly on the same days as the courts of jus- 
 tice; that is to say, every day, with the exception of the festi- 
 vals, which were the only holidays the senators had; and con- 
 sequently the number of days on which they sat was about 
 three hundred"^ The annual expense therefore amounted to 
 25 talents. In what manner the wages of the senate were paid, 
 we are not informed; probably by prytaneias. When the Four 
 Hundred abolished the democracy, and drove the senate out of 
 the senate-house, they gave the senators the whole pay for the 
 rest of the year in advance^^^ 
 
 Chapter XV. 
 
 Pay of the Courts of Justice, 
 
 The largest item among the salaries regularly paid in time of 
 peace was the wages of the dicasts {fMccrOos BiKaarLKos). The 
 introduction of these is ascribed to Pericles by Aristotle"% on 
 
 ^^^ Aristoph. Eccl. 290 and 381. 
 
 ^^^ Hesych. in v. ^ovKrjs 'Kax^'iv, Xe- 
 noph. Hell. ii. 3, 18, and his commen- 
 tators. 
 
 ^^* Cf. Aristoph. Thesmoph. 85. The 
 senate originally sat on some feast- 
 days, and was not released from these 
 duties till later times, as is shown by 
 the document in A then. iv. p. 171 E. 
 
 3'** Thucyd. viii. 69. 
 
 356 Polit. ii. 10. It is therefore xm- 
 necessary to refute the Append. Pro v. 
 Vatic, iii. 35, which attributes the first 
 institution of this pay to Callistratus. 
 [The passage in the Politics referred 
 to, TO. de 8iKa(TTr]piajiiardo<p6pa Karea- 
 TTjCTf HepiKkrji, is from a chapter which 
 appears not to be the production of 
 
 Aristotle (see Gottling ad loc. p. 345 ; 
 another statement in the same chapter 
 is called in question by the author him- 
 self, vol. ii. p. 261); the fact is how- 
 ever confirmed by Plutarch. Pericl. 9, 
 Kai Toxy BecopiKols Kol diKacTTiKols ^rjp.- 
 fxatri .... crvvbeKaaas to TrXrjdos, &c. 
 The testimony of the Scholiast to 
 Aristophanes (Vesp. 682), cited in the 
 next note, seems to be unfairly made 
 use of. It is as follows : tov <f)6pov 
 Xeyei d(fi (ov ibiboro to Tpi<a^o\ov. 
 TovTO be tiWoTC aWas cbiboro, twp br}- 
 fxayayyo^v Tci 7r\r}dr] KoXaKcvovTOiPf as 
 (f>Tjcnv ^ ApKTTOTfXrjs ev IloXiT flats, i.e, 
 wages were given to the dicasts at dif- 
 ferent rates at different times, the dema- 
 gogues flattering the populace ^ as Arts-
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PAY OF THE COURTS OF JUSTICE. 
 
 233 
 
 whose accurate acquaintance with antiquity perfect rehance can 
 be placed. And from the testimony of the same writer we 
 learn that the wages of the dicasts did not remain the same^ 
 but underwent some change^". What then were these altera- 
 tions, and when did they take place? 
 
 Strepsiades says in the Clouds^^^ that he had given the first 
 heliastic obolus to his son, when he was six years old, to buy a 
 little cart; hence we learn that originally the pay of the dicasts 
 amounted to an obolus; and since in Olymp. 89, 1 (b.c. 424), 
 the child is represented in the Clouds as a practised rider, this 
 obolus must have been introduced for at least four Olympiads. 
 The Scholiast tells us that the wages of the dicasts amounted 
 to 2 oboliin the time of the Frogs of Aristophanes; it is also 
 stated that they were a drachma at the same period^". With 
 regard to the latter statement, there is evidently a confusion 
 either with the drachma of the diaetetse, or with the pay of the 
 advocates {^lctOo^ crvvrjyopLKos), of which latter Aristophanes 
 speaks in a passage that the Scholiast perhaps referred to the 
 wages of the dicasts. But no traces occur of their wages ever 
 having been 2 oboH, except a vague report in the Scholiast to 
 the Birds, that the dicasts had for a time received 2 oboli; 
 
 totle says in the Politics j viz. iv. 4, 6 dr]- 
 fiayaryos Koi 6 Koka^ ol avTol Koi dva- 
 \oyou, &.C.; aud v, 11, dio Koi 6 KoXa^ 
 nap' afj,(poT€pois evTifios' rrapa p.kv rots 
 hr]p.ois 6 dT}p,aya>yos, ecrri yap 6 br^p-a- 
 yoiyos tov drjpov KoKa^. No objection 
 can be made from the use of the plural 
 IloXiretatj; for Aristotle himself says 
 iv. 7, cl)(77rep nXdrcov iv rals EToXtre/ais. 
 The same expression with regard to 
 the variable rate of the dicasts' wages 
 is used by Hesychius, without any 
 mention of Aristotle : diKaariKov' 
 'ApiaTO(pdvT}s €v''Q,pais rpiw^okov (Prjcriv 
 fiuai' ov pevTOL €(TTr)Kev, aXX' aXKore 
 aXXcoff ibihoTO. Transl.] 
 
 ^^' Schol. Aristoph. Yesp. 682, fi-om 
 Aristotle's State of Athens; Schol. 
 Nub. 861; Plut. 329; Av. 1540; He- 
 sych. in v. diKaariKov, Suidas in v. 
 
 rjXiacrTal. Concerning the expression 
 of the grammarians compare Hem- 
 sterhuis ad Plut. ut sup. Petit as 
 usual (iii. 1, 3,) founds a false view of 
 the subject upon a false interpretation 
 of the Scholiast of Aristophanes. 
 
 3'« Vs. 861. 
 
 ^'^ Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 141, (Cf. 
 Schol. Vesp. 658, concerning the 
 drachma.) Welcker, at the above 
 passage in the Frogs, allows that the 
 triobolon may have been introduced 
 previously, but he prefers adhering to 
 the explanation of the Scholiast, as he 
 thinks that Aristophanes mentions 2 
 oboli according to the ancient usage, 
 although they received 3 at that 
 time. This is not very probable, and 
 I do not doubt that he will prefer my 
 interpretation.
 
 234 
 
 PAY OF THE COURTS OF JUSTICE. 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 either the grammarian inferred this from the words of Aristo- 
 phanes (w9 fjue^ya BvvaaOov Travrap^ou rco Bv^ o^oXoo), or he had 
 heard something of the diobeha, and supposed it was the wages 
 of the dicasts. But the words of Aristophanes unquestionably 
 refer to the diobeha. That this was in full force in Olymp. 92, 
 3 (b.c. 410), we know from the Choiseul Inscription, and why 
 should it not have been equally so in Olymp. 93, 3 (b.c. 406), 
 the year in which the comedy of the Frogs was acted? If the 
 wages of the dicasts had been raised before this time to 3 
 oboli, no one will suppose that the Athenians would have 
 lowered this rate in opposition to their pecuniary interest; and 
 in fact we find that it had been introduced previously. In the 
 Birds of Aristophanes^^**, which was acted in Olymp. 91, 2 
 (b.c. 415), the triobolon occurs as the wages of the dicasts, as is 
 proved by the connexion with the Colacretse; and indeed it is 
 mentioned at a much earlier date, viz., in the Knights (Olymp. 
 88, 4, B.C. 425), and the Wasps (Olymp. 89, 2, b.c. 423)^'^ 
 In both plays Cleon is the chief object of ridicule, and in the 
 Knights he is distinctly mentioned as the favourer of the trio- 
 bolon^^^; in the latter comedy he boasts that he would always 
 take care that it did not fail; and he flatters the people by tell- 
 ing them that, according to ancient oracles, the pay of the 
 dicasts would be in Arcadia as high as 5 oboli; i. e. as the 
 Scholiast adds, when the Peloponnese should be conquered^^^ 
 If we add to this the testimony of the Scholiast to the Plutus^***, 
 it follows with certainty that none other than this noxious 
 demagogue, at the time of his greatest power, about the 88th 
 Olympiad (b.c. 428), raised the wages of the dicasts from 1 
 to 3 oboli ^ From this it seems that the rate of payment 
 
 360 Vs. 1540. 
 
 3«i Eq. 51, 255; Vesp. 607,682,688, 
 797,1116. 
 
 ^^■' Eq. 257. 
 
 3^3 Eq. 797- This passage has been 
 strangely misunderstood by Spanheim 
 (ad Nub. 861,) who has inferred from 
 it that in Arcadia the pay of the 
 dicasts amounted to 5 oboli. The 
 Arcadians probably never thought of 
 
 the dicasts' wages ; but Cleon forcibly 
 represents to the Athenians the exten- 
 sion of their jurisdiction to the middle 
 of the Peloponnese, and its conse- 
 quence, a plentiful harvest of money. 
 
 2^^ Vs. 330, which, although ad- 
 duced in an improper place, should be 
 referred to the pay of the dicasts. 
 
 ' [Zcnobius and Photius in v. vnep 
 Tct KaWiKparovs — ^ ApKTToreXrjs 6c
 
 CH. XV.] PAY OF THE COURTS OF JUSTICE. 
 
 235 
 
 never was at 2 oboli ; yet Pollux^", as well as the Scholiast to 
 Aristophanes^ appears to have believed in its existencQ, Other- 
 wise the grammarians^ in speaking of the wages of the dicasts, 
 generally mention 3 oboli^ at the same time recognising their 
 mutability^^^ The hero Lycus, under whose protection the 
 system of judicature was placed^ regularly received his 3 oboli, 
 if he had a sanctuary in the court of justice^^^. 
 
 The payment of the wages of the dicasts, which was the 
 duty of the colacretse, took place at each sitting of the court^®% 
 in the following manner. Besides the judicial staff, each person 
 received at his entrance into the court a small tablet (called 
 avfM/3o\ov) ; at the close of the sitting he gave this to the pry- 
 tanes, and received the money for it; whoever came late into 
 court ran the risk of receiving nothing^^^ The prytaneia were 
 first appointed for defraying the expense ; if these were not suf- 
 ficient (and how could they ever have been so), the other branches 
 of the revenue contributed, particularly the fines, and probably 
 in ancient times the tributes^^**. Aristophanes reckons the 
 annual amount at 150 talents, assuming 300 days on which the 
 courts sat, and 6000 dicasts a day who received the triobo- 
 
 (})r](nv iv Tji *A9T]vaia)v TroXireia KaXXt- 
 Kpdrrju Tiva npoiTOV Tovs biKaariKovs 
 fiKxdovs {diKaarcov tovs yuaOovs Zen.) 
 €is vrrep^oXrjv av^rjaai. From tlie ex- 
 pression " a certain Callicrates, KaX- 
 XiKpdrrjv TLva,'^ it seems that the in- 
 creaser of the dicasts' wages could not 
 have been a well-known person. Cal- 
 listratus, the son of Callicrates, flou- 
 rished about the 100th Olympiad (see 
 above p. 229); his father therefore 
 might have earned this measure ten 
 Olympiads before that time; which 
 nearly agrees with the date given in 
 the text for the supposed increase by 
 Cleon. — Transl.] 
 
 ^^^ viii. 113. According to the ex- 
 planation of Spanheim ut sup., which, 
 as I have above mentioned, I prefer to 
 that of Meui-sius, without however 
 believing the account of Pollux, as 
 Spanheim does. 
 
 366 Pollux viii. 20 ; Hesych. in v. 
 diKaa-TiKov ; Suid. in v. rjXiaa-Tai and 
 ^aKTqpla ; Schol. Aristoph. in the pas- 
 sages quoted above and Plut. 277; 
 Suid. and Phot, in v. crvp-^oXov ; Schol. 
 Demosth. in Reisk. Demosth. vol. ii. 
 p. 131; Lucian. Bis Accus. 12 and 15. 
 Several other passages, as e. g. Hesy- 
 chius in v. o^okoi, I omit, as they con- 
 tain nothing to make them worth 
 quoting. 
 
 ^^'^ See Hudtwalcker von den Diii- 
 teten, p. 14. 
 
 ^^^ Lucian. ut sup. 
 
 369 Schol. Aristoph. Plut. 277, whose 
 infoiTuation is chiefly taken from Aris- 
 totle's State of Athens quoted by the 
 Scholiast at v. 278; also Suidas in v. 
 /SaKTiypta; Etymol. in v. avfi^oXov ; 
 Pollux viii. 16; Aristoph. Vesp. 710. 
 
 ^70 Cf. Schol. Aristoph. Vesp. 682.
 
 236 
 
 PAY OF THE COURTS OF JUSTICE. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 Ion"' ; and that the expense was not small we learn from other 
 sources. It is, however, to be remarked, that Aristophanes, in 
 forming his calculation, has taken the dicasts at 6000, their 
 highest number, who did not perform their duties every day. 
 Six thousand were appointed for each year ; and from these the 
 dicasts were first selected for each particular cause, and it was 
 not till they were actually assigned to some court that they 
 received pay. The ten regular courts of justice at Athens, con- 
 sisting each of 500 dicasts, required only the daily attendance of 
 5000^'^ Now it is true that large tribunals occur of 1000, 
 1500, 2000, and even 6000 dicasts; but, on the other hand, 
 small ones of 201, 401, &c.^". It is therefore possible that the 
 expense was something less than Aristophanes states it ; I am 
 willing however to allow his estimate to pass as an approxima- 
 tion to the truth, when applied to the times preceding the 
 anarchy, and to compute the expenses of jurisdiction generally at 
 150 talents, particularly as many small expenses, in addition to 
 the pay of the dicasts, must necessarily have been incurred in 
 the courts ; but after the archonship of Euclid, when the allies 
 had revolted, it is not possible that there could have been so 
 many dicasts, and the cost must therefore have been less. 
 And as in time of war the courts did not always continue sit- 
 ting^'*, these expenses occasionally ceased. 
 
 The wages of the disetetae were not provided out of the 
 public money ; these persons were paid for each separate cause 
 by the litigant parties themselves. The dieetetee received a 
 drachma from the plaintiff at the commencement of the suit, 
 and again the same sum from both parties at the Antomosia, and 
 at every Hypomosia^"'. A grammarian of mean authority 
 
 37^ Vesp. 660 sqq. and the Scholiast. 
 About sixty holidays, on which the 
 courts did not sit, are not too many for 
 Athens; this leaves 300 sitting-days. 
 But I am not able to find any con- 
 firmation of Hudtwalcker's supposition 
 (von den Diateten, p. 30), that the 
 courts did not sit through the whole 
 of Scirophorion. 
 
 =»7=2 See Matthias Miscell. Philog. 
 vol. i. p. 2oI sqq. ; comp. also p. 158. 
 
 ^^^ Besides Matthiae see Polhix 
 viii. 53 and 48; Lex. Seg. p. 310, 30, 
 and p. 189, 20 ; Phot, in v. TjXiaia. 
 
 ^'^ Lys. Trepi 8r]iJ.ocr. ddiK. p. 590. 
 
 ^'* This is the TrapdaTacris or napa- 
 Kardorao-ty, Pollux viii. 39, 127; Har- 
 pocrat. in v. Trapdaracns, and thence 
 Suidas, Photius, and Lex. Seg. p. 290, 
 298. IlapaKaTdo-Taa-ii occurs in Pho- 
 tius, EtymoL, and Lex. Seg. See 
 Hudtwalckcr von den Diiit. p. 14 sqq.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 PAY OF THE COURTS OF JUSTICE. 
 
 237 
 
 states^^' that the disetetae arbitrated many law-suits, and that the 
 public authorities employed every possible means to prevent 
 the sitting of the courts, in order that the state might not be 
 compelled to expend so much money upon the wages of the 
 dicasts ; but, judging from the disposition of the Athenians, we 
 can at the most believe that such a motive might have influenced 
 them at seasons of the greatest national distress; for in ordinary 
 times it was customary to allow pecuniary largesses for the main- 
 tenance of the people. 
 
 Chapter XVI. 
 
 On certain other Persons receiving Salaries from the Public 
 Revenue. 
 
 The wages of the public advocates or orators [fxia-Oos o-vvrjyo- 
 pLKos) occasioned a small expense, which amounted every day, 
 i. e, for the 300 days of business, to a drachma, and not for each 
 speech, as the Scholiast of Aristophanes erroneously asserts^". 
 As these advocates were ten in number, the whole expense 
 amounted to half a talent a year. 
 
 The ambassadors also received a stipend in ancient times ; 
 and although resident embassies (a practice first introduced by 
 the French) were unknown, they may nevertheless be reckoned 
 among the regular expenses, since ambassadors were very fre- 
 quently despatched to foreign states ; and when they travelled 
 to a distance, as, for example, to Persia, were necessarily absent 
 for a long time. The ambassadors to Philip of Macedon 
 attended him even on marches and journeys^'^. Ambassadors, 
 during the time that they were able to have a fixed residence, 
 were never compelled to live at their own expense ; they were 
 supported by presents which they received both in free states^^^ 
 and in countries where the government was monarchical. It 
 
 ^''® Schol. Demosth. ap. Reisk. ut 
 sup. to which statement Hudtwalcker 
 assents, p. 34. 
 
 377 Aristoph. Vesp. 689, and the 
 Scholiast. 
 
 ^'« Demosth. Philipp. iii. p. 113, 18. 
 
 379 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 393, 
 25 ; Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 629 ; 
 ^lian. Var. Hist. i. 22 ; Decree of 
 the Arcadians in Crete in Chishull's 
 Ant. Asiat. p. 118.
 
 238 
 
 ON CERTAIN OTHER PERSONS RECEIVING [bK. II. 
 
 may be seen from the speech of Demosthenes for the Crown, that 
 in the Greek cities they were not only honoured with the first 
 l^lace in the theatres, but were hospitably entertained, and gene- 
 rally resided at the house of the proxenus, although an instance 
 occurs of an embassy to Phihp having for particular reasons pre- 
 ferred the public inn^^°. The treasurer, however, usually paid 
 them a sum in advance for thirty days, as travelling money 
 (icpoScov, TTopeiovY^K In the time of Aristophanes, the ambas- 
 sadors received 2 or 3 drachmas a day^^^ The highest pay 
 which we meet with, such indeed as never was given in any 
 other state, is 1000 drachmas, which was received by five 
 Athenian ambassadors who were sent to Philip. These ambas- 
 sadors remained absent three months, although they might have 
 equally well returned at the end of one^°^ In general the 
 Athenians sent ten ambassadors, but occasionally not more 
 than two or three. 
 
 The sophronistae, or inspectors of the youths in the training 
 schools, of whom there were ten annually elected by chei- 
 rotonia, one from each tribe, received a daily stipend of 1 
 drachma^^"* ; the episcopi also, who were sent to subject states. 
 
 '»<» Orat. de Halon. p. 81, 19; 
 Xenoph. Hell. v. 4, 22 ; Dem. de Fals. 
 Leg. p. 390, 26. 
 
 ^^' Casaub. and Tlieoph. Char. xi. ; 
 Etymol. in v. iropiiov, Chand. Inscript. 
 ii. 12. 
 
 ^^■^ Acliarn. 65, and from the con- 
 text 602. 
 
 383 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 390. 
 That there were only five of them is 
 evident from the decree in Demosth. 
 pro Corona, p. 235. Demosthenes was 
 indeed one of the number, but his 
 name is not in the decree, and there- 
 fore the 1000 drachmas should only be 
 referred to the five mentioned in it, 
 unless a subsequent decree was framed, 
 and other ambassadors were appointed 
 in addition to the fonner. ;My space 
 liowever does not permit me to treat 
 of this point at full length, particu- 
 larly as there are gi-eat chronological 
 difficulties connected with it. 
 
 ^«^ Lex. Seg. p. 301 ; Phot, in v. 
 aaxppovio-Tai, cf. Etym. in v. in the 
 two latter read iKaar-qs cj^vX^s eh. The 
 words of the Etjinologist are both in 
 Phavorinus and Stobseus. See Fis- 
 cher's Ind. ^scliin. in v. acocfipovLcrTai, 
 where however, together with Hem- 
 sterhuis ad Pol. viii. 138, he falsely 
 assumes that there were 100 sophro- 
 nistae, from the incorrect reading in 
 the gi-ammarians above quoted. In 
 the times of the emperors there were 
 only 6, and probably the same number 
 of hyposophronistae, who entered their 
 office together at the beginning of the 
 month Boedromion, as may be con- 
 cluded from Corp. Inscript. No. 276, 
 cf. 271, 272. The Gloss refers to De- 
 mosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 433, 3, where 
 however there is only an allusion to 
 this office, which is also mentioned in 
 the Axiochus, p. 367 A.
 
 CH. XVI.] SALARIES FROM THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 239 
 
 received a salar)^, probably at the cost of the cities over which 
 they presided^"^. 
 
 The nomothetee, a legislative commission consisting of 501, 
 1001, or 1501 persons, who w^ere selected from those who had 
 been dicasts, also perhaps received a stipend ; for in their 
 former capacity they had been accustomed to the triobolon ; 
 and the senate was commanded by law to administer the money 
 for the nomothet8e^^^ 
 
 The collection of the public revenue did not require any paid 
 officers, as it was let out in farm ; even when the senate found 
 it necessary to appoint a collector, in order to enforce payment 
 of the farmers, he could scarcely have been paid. 
 
 All the servants of the different authorities received salaries, 
 for example, the prometretce^^' ; it is however probable that 
 these officers w^ere paid by the sellers of the commodities mea- 
 sured. Originally there was an important distinction between 
 service [virTjpeG-ia) and an office of government {dpxv) 5 the 
 former received a salary, the latter none. The heralds and 
 clerks particularly deserve notice ; since certain heralds, as well 
 as the clerk of the senate, the clerk of the senate and people, 
 and the checking-clerk and under- clerk of the senate, were fed 
 at the cost of the state in the tholus or prytaneum^°% where 
 doubtless they also resided. 
 
 To the transcribers of the laws a stipend was allowed for a 
 fixed time, mthin which they were bound to complete their 
 labours^^^ ; and a particular sum of money was set apart for 
 engraving the decrees^^". 
 
 The large amount of the salary of the physicians and the pay ot 
 the singers and musicians at Athens and in other places, has been 
 shown in the first book^^^ And how great must have been the 
 number of persons whom the state remunerated for their services 
 (either by its own means or by those of subordinate corporations), 
 such as citharists, gymnasts, and others of the same description. 
 
 3^5 Aristoph. Av. 1023 sqq. 
 2«« Petit Leg. Att. ii. 1, 1. See Wolf 
 Proleg. ad Lept. p. cxLvii. 
 ^^' Harpocrat. in it pokier p-qrai 
 ^^^ See the inscriptions quoted in 
 
 book ii. ch. 8, and Demosth. de Fals. 
 Leg. p. 419, 25. 
 
 ^^^ Lysias c. Nicom. 
 
 ^s*' Book ii. ch. 6. 
 
 3^1 Chap. 21
 
 240 
 
 ON CERTAIN OTHER PERSONS RECEIVING QbK. IT. 
 
 The poets also received a salary, which was allowed them by 
 the Senate of Five Hundred ; and we have reason to suppose 
 that its amount was not inconsiderable ; for Agyrrhius having 
 been offended, as it seems, by the ridicule of comic poets, 
 thought it worth while to persuade the people to reduce it^®*. 
 
 Lastly, several hundred sailors received regular pay in time 
 of peace. In early times the Athenians had two sacred tri- 
 remes, the Paralos, the crew of which bore the name of 
 Paralitse [TrapaXiraL, also TrdpaXoc), and the Salaminia or 
 Delia (sometimes simply called Theoris), and its crew were 
 named Salaminians'^' : the latter vessel belonged to the De- 
 lian theoria; and both these triremes, as being quick sailers, 
 were used for other theorias, as well as for embassies and 
 for the transport of money and persons; in battles also, 
 and then they conveyed the admiral. That the crew of the 
 Paralos, though it w^as mostly in harbour, always received 4 
 oboli a day, we know from distinct testimony^^*; and as the 
 Salaminia performed the same services, we may without any 
 hesitation assume that the Salaminians received the same pay. 
 The pay of the trireme-crews having been generally calculated 
 by estimating the wages of 200 common sailors, the pay of 
 two triremes at 4 oboli a man per day: for a year reckoned at 
 365 days (the intercalary month being divided among the 
 several years) will amount to 16 talents 1333 drachmas 2 oboli. 
 In latter times we meet with a trireme named Ammonis, which 
 is undoubtedly different from the two first ; and an Antigonis 
 and a Demetrias, so called no doubt from the names of those 
 much honoured kings ; and finally, a Ptolemais^®*, of which it is 
 
 392 Schol. Eccl. 102; Aristoph. Ran. 
 370 ; and the Scholiast. Archinus is 
 mentioned in the last Scholium; but 
 the Scholiast on the Ecclesiazusae ap- 
 pears better informed ; and perhaps 
 Archinus is only an error of the tran- 
 scriber for Agyrrhius. 
 
 393 Concerning both these vessels see 
 Sigon. R. A. iv. 5. In Photius (in v. 
 TrapaXoi) the Salaminia and the Pa- 
 ralos are stated to be the same ship, 
 which is false. But in the word nd- 
 
 paXos, and in the first article of irapa- 
 Xoi, they are correctly distinguished. 
 Concerning the name of the crew see 
 Pollux viii. 116; Hesych. in v. Trapa- 
 XiTTjs. Concerning the Delia vid. ad 
 Inscript. 151, § 1. 
 
 39* Harpocrat. and Phot, in v. nd- 
 paXos. 
 
 39* Harpocrat. and Suidas in v. 'A/x- 
 fi<ovh, and there Maussac, Lex. Seg. 
 p. 267 ; Phot, in v. ndpaXoi and nd- 
 paXos.
 
 CH. XVI.] SALARIES FROM THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 241 
 
 probable, that like the tribe Ptolemais, it only succeeded in the 
 place of the Antigonis or the Demetrias. We are not informed 
 how the pay of these vessels was regulated; but as the 
 Ammonis had a treasurer, it is probable the others had the 
 same, and since the Ammonis served in time of peace, it must 
 occasionally have had sailors w^ho then received pay. 
 
 I -will presently speak of two other kinds of salaries paid in 
 time of peace, the pay of the cavalry, and the maintenance of 
 the infirm, which was also called ^icrOos or pay^^^; all these 
 taken together caused a considerable expense. In order, how- 
 ever, to produce some diminution in the amount, and to prevent 
 any person from obtaining greater emoluments from the state 
 than was fair, the law ordered that no one should receive pay 
 from more than one source [firj hixoOev fJnaOocfyopelv) ^^\ Thus 
 the wages of the dicasts, orators, ecclesiasts, senators, soldiers, 
 sailors, cavalry, in short all salaries whatever, precluded any 
 person from receiving pay for other services upon the same day. 
 
 The grammarians assert that pay was given out by pry- 
 taneias^^% a statement which is incorrect in this general sense. 
 For the dicasts and the assembly were (as well as the theorica) 
 paid by the day, the soldiers and sailors in war by the month ; 
 but of all other persons receiving salaries it may have been 
 true. Nothing seems more natural than that the Senate of 
 Five Hundred, the orators, clerks, and other inferior officers, 
 should have been paid by prytaneias ; with regard to the main- 
 tenance of the infirm, this was certainly the regulation, and 
 for the cavalry and sailors in the time of peace we may suppose 
 that it was adopted for the sake of uniformity. This mode of 
 payment was also the most convenient for passing the accounts, 
 which took place in every prytaneia. 
 
 35" ^sch. c. Timarch. p. 123. 
 
 397 Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 739, C- 
 Petit alone (Leg. Att. v. C, 2,) has be- 
 lieved the absurd idea of Ulpian, that 
 this means a prohibition to follow 
 more than one occupation at the same 
 time. 
 
 "^^ Ammonius and from him Thomas 
 
 INIag. in v. npvTavelov. Hesychius in 
 the same word savs that t] eVt {x-qvi 
 fiiado(f)opia is also called TvpvTave^ov, 
 which probably means the pay of the 
 prytanes and the other senators, which 
 was paid by prytaneias, for in later 
 times the prytaneias coincided with 
 the months.
 
 242 
 
 RELIEF OF THE DESTITUTE. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 Chapter XVIL 
 
 Relief of the Destitute. 
 
 The maintenance of those citizens, who on account of bodily- 
 defects or infirmities were unable to obtain a livelihood [ahv- 
 varoi), was a laudable institution. This practice however, as 
 well as the custom of supporting children whose fathers had 
 died in war, until they reached the age of manhood'^% belonged 
 exclusively to the Athenians, as charity was a virtue rarely met 
 wdth among the Greeks. 
 
 With regard to the maintenance of persons who had been 
 mutilated in war, Pisistratus is mentioned as the originator of 
 this custom"'^ ; an account which has every probability, since 
 Pisistratus was of a mild disposition, and usurpers are generally 
 glad to seize every opportunity of conferring a benefit, with a 
 view to make themselves popular; nor would the Athenians 
 with their hatred of tyranny have attributed this honour to him, 
 if he had not deserved it. According to others'*"^ this provision 
 derived its origin from a law of Solon, who certainly gave the 
 example to Pisistratus by the proposal being made, as Hera- 
 clides in Plutarch informs us, for the benefit of an individual. 
 In early times Athens could boast of having no citizen in want 
 of the necessaries of life, nor did any one ever disgrace the 
 nation by begging''"^; but after the Peloponnesian war, poverty 
 made itself everywhere manifest ; and no small number stood 
 in need of this assistance, if they were infirm or maimed. The 
 bounty was restricted by law to persons whose property was 
 under 3 minas"*"^ ; but even in the age of Socrates an income of 
 this amount was very inconsiderable ; and, accordingly, all 
 
 355 Aristid. Panath. vol. i. p. 331, 
 ed. Cant. [Aristotle however (Pol. 
 ii. 5,) states that in his time this last 
 institution existed in other states ex- 
 cept Athens : eort 8e Koi iv raty 'A^^- 
 vais ovTOS 6 vofios vvv Koi iv ire pais 
 
 TbiV TToKeOOV. TllANSL.] 
 
 ^"'^ Plutarch. Solon. 31. 
 
 ^"^ Schol. yEschin. ap. Taylor, ad 
 Lys. vol. V. p. 739, ed. Reisk. et ap. 
 Reisk. vol. iii. p. 738. 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. Areop. 38. 
 
 "^"^ Ilarpocrat. Suid. Hesych. and 
 the above-quoted passages of tlie 
 Lexica in Taylor, ut sup. and tlie 
 couimcntators upon Ilcsychius.
 
 CH. XVII.] 
 
 RELIEF OF THE DESTITUTE. 
 
 243 
 
 those who received this bounty were in fact nearly destitute. 
 The Athenians however do not seem to have been very sparing 
 of this donative ; the individual for whom Lysias""^ wrote his 
 speech in order to prove that he was deserving of this support, 
 carried on certainly some trade^ although he asserts it was not 
 sufficient to maintain him, and it appears that he rode occasion- 
 ally, although indeed not upon his own horse, and also because 
 he was unable to walk without the help of crutches. This 
 bounty was awarded by a decree of the people*"*; but the 
 examination of the individuals belonged to the Senate of Five 
 Hundred*"^ ; the payments were made by prytaneias ; conse- 
 quently, if any one deferred his examination in one prytaneia 
 he was obliged to wait till the next"^ 
 
 The unpublished Scholiast to iEschines, who is quoted by 
 Taylor in his notes, states that this bounty amounted to 3 
 oboli a day ; here then we again meet with the triobolon of the 
 dicasts, which is always crossing the path of the grammarians. 
 The money paid to the infirm was never more than 2 oboli or 
 less than 1 : between these two rates ancient writers are 
 divided; the obvious supposition is that some received more 
 than others, according as their necessities were more or less 
 urgent ; but a closer consideration teaches us that the difi'erence 
 refers only to the times. In the time of Lysias 1 obolus was 
 given*"^ ; afterwards, when the difficulty of procuring subsistence 
 had increased, this rate was doubled. The time at which this 
 increase took place may be nearly ascertained from the gram- 
 marians. Harpocration*°^ states " that the infirm or impotent 
 (dBvvaToi) received 2 oboli a day, as some say, or 1 obolus, as 
 Aristotle in the Constitution of Athens states; but, as Philo- 
 
 ^"* Ilfpt Tov ddwdrov. This speech 
 is written in such a jesting tone, that 
 I consider it to be a mere rhetorical 
 exercise, which was never deUvered: 
 at least the Athenians must have been 
 very much astonished at the jocu- 
 larity of this poor man when petition- 
 ing for a pecuniary allowance. 
 
 405 Herald. Anim. in Salm. Observ. 
 ad I. A. et R. iii. 8,4. 
 
 ^»« iEschin. c. Timarch. p. 123 ; ITar- 
 pocrat. Suid. Ilesych. ; and a Lexicon 
 in the Bibl. Coislin. p. G03, p. 238. 
 
 '"'^ yEschin. ut sup. 
 
 ''•'« Lys. ut sup. p. 749, p. 7^8. 
 
 ^^^ In v. dbvpciToi, where the right 
 reading is preserved in the Paris AIS. 
 in Bast's Epist.Crit. p. ,176, 8vo o^oXovs 
 rrjs rjixefjai ol fiev ^acriv eKdarijs. 
 
 R 2
 
 244 
 
 RELIEF OF THE DESTITUTE. 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 chorus says, 9 drachmas every month.'^ Suidas gives the 
 same account from Philochorus^'" ; Hesychius mentions 2 
 oboli without any further limitation. In Suidas and other 
 lexicons"";, it is stated that some received 1, and others 2 oboh; 
 but Bast has proved that the reading in Suidas is erroneous; and 
 according to the true reading the grammarian says that some 
 writers mention that they received 1, and others 2 ; it is evi- 
 dent, therefore, that the error should be corrected in the same 
 manner in the other Lexicons. We see from these passages that 
 Aristotle, as well as Lysias, spoke only of 1 obolus"'^ ; and we 
 may thence infer that up to the time of the latter this bounty 
 was not greater; it must therefore have been subsequently 
 raised, perhaps, between the times of Aristotle and Philochorus, 
 who was a youth when Eratosthenes was an old man. For the 
 statement of Philochorus is the same in substance with the other 
 account, that they received 2 ol^oli a day ; which for the month 
 of twenty-nine days gives 9 drachmas 4 oboli; the latter the 
 grammarians omit. Philochorus^s computation by months 
 proves of itself that he is speaking of later times, when the pry- 
 taneias coincided with the months ; it does not however follow 
 from this that the increase did not take place before the intro- 
 duction of the twelve tribes. 
 
 If we could now ascertain how many upon an average were 
 in need of this bounty, an estimate of the expense might be 
 made ; but the assumption of Meursius that they amounted to 
 500, is founded upon a false reading in Suidas" '\ Considering, 
 however, the necessitous condition of most of the Athenian 
 
 ^'" In V. aBvparoi, comp. Zonaras in 
 V. ddvvaToi. The Lexicon in the Bibl. 
 Coisl. p. G03, falsely charges Philo- 
 chorus Avith saying that they received 
 5 oboli a day ; but there is an error of 
 the copyist, viz. e' instead of eWea 
 8paxfJ.cis, as Albei'ti has shown by the 
 comparison and correction of Bibl. 
 Coisl. p. 2.38. 
 
 *'^ Suid. in v. ddvvaroi, Zonaras, 
 and the Lexicon in Bibl. Coisl. p. 230. 
 In Suidas it should be written ol fxev 
 (paaiv iKuarr)^ rjfiepas U/SoXovs dvo, ol 
 
 Se 6l3o\6v. See Bast's Epist. Crit. 
 
 p. no. 
 
 ^'^ For although the Lexicon in 
 Bibl. Coisl. p. G03, represents Aris- 
 totle to have said that they received 2 
 oboli, -without making any mention of 
 one, this is an evident error, which is 
 not worth the trouble of refutation. 
 
 "'^ :Mcurs. Lect. Att. vi. 5. The 
 passage in Suidas which others thought 
 that they had corrected, was first in- 
 geniously emended by Bast. Epist. 
 Crit. p. 17G.
 
 CH. XV 
 
 •] 
 
 RELIEF OF THE DESTITUTE. 
 
 245 
 
 citizens^ and the frequency of wars, 500 may be assumed as he 
 lowest number of the old, blind, lame, sick, and maimed, who 
 were to be maintained ; and the expense of their maintenance, 
 according as we reckon it at 1 or 2 oboli a head, may be at the 
 lowest estimated at 5 or 10 talents. To this must be added 
 the support of the orphan children, whose fathers had perished 
 in war ; for whose instruction also the state provided until their 
 eighteenth year, in order that their education might be com- 
 pleted before they were sent forth, provided with a complete 
 suit of armour"' \ That the number of orphans, after so many 
 wars, was considerable, might have been assumed without the 
 authority of Isocrates*'\ 
 
 The support which private individuals procured by means of 
 a particular agreement which they made by entering into a 
 society [epavos] differed from public maintenance""'. The 
 society itself and the money subscribed were each called Eranos, 
 the members Eranistse, their whole number, the community of 
 the Eranistse [to kolvov twv epavto-rcov), and their president an 
 Eranarch. Their objects were of the most various description; 
 if some friends wanted to provide a dinner, or a corporation to 
 celebrate a solemnity, to give a banquet, or forward any parti- 
 cular purpose by bribery"'^, the expense was defrayed by an 
 eranos. Associations of this kind were very common in the 
 democratic states of Greece, and to this class the numberless 
 political and religious societies, corporations, unions for com- 
 merce and shipping, belonged : many of them, more particularly 
 the religious associations {6 tacroi), were possessed of land'''^ and 
 like states and subordinate corporations they had power to make 
 decrees, which they recorded upon stone"' ^; and lastly, there 
 were laws concerning these societies {kpavuKol vofxoi), and law- 
 
 ^'•» Comp. Petit Leg. Att. viii. 3, 6. 
 
 *^^ Su/A/xax- 29. 
 
 ^^'^ I only mention this subject in a 
 few words : several early writers have 
 treated on it at full length, who mu- 
 tually correct one another, of Avhich the 
 chief are, Tetit Leg. Att. v. 7, 1 ; Sal- 
 masius de Usuris chap. 3; Defens. 
 
 Misc. chap. 1 sqq.; Herald. Observ. 
 chap. 43 ; Animadv. in Salmas. Observ. 
 ad I. A. et Rom. vi. 1 — 8. 
 
 ^'7 Demosth. pro Corona, p. 329, 15. 
 
 ^'» Pseud- Aristot. CEcon. ii. 2, 3. 
 
 "^^ See for example Corp. Inscript. 
 Nos. 109,110.
 
 246 
 
 PUBLIC REWARDS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 suits called after their name [ipavLKoX hUai), in which, as well 
 as in the commercial causes, a more rapid course of justice was 
 prescribed'^*'. A peculiar kind of eranos is that which was made 
 for the support of the destitute citizens ; it was founded upon 
 the principle of mutual assistance, and it was expected that the 
 members who had l^een relieved should pay the money back 
 again when they had raised themselves to better circum- 
 stances**'. 
 
 Chapter XVIII. 
 
 Public Rewards, 
 
 A SMALL expense was occasioned by one part of the pubUc 
 rewards and marks of honour. Under this head may be men- 
 tioned the public entertainments {airrjcns iv irpvTaveia)), which 
 many others, besides the fifty prytanes and certain inferior offi- 
 cers, received as a mark of distinction, and which must have cost 
 2 or 3 talents a year. The donation of the golden crown {are- 
 <f>avos) was by no means a rare occurrence ; the Senate of Five 
 Hundred, if it performed its duties honestly, was presented with 
 a crown every year*^^; nations gave crowns to one another, and 
 private individuals were frequently crowned by the state : how 
 great was the weight of these golden crowns has been already 
 shewn''^^ In ancient times however they were not frequently 
 given ; those who after the anarchy brought back the people 
 from Phyle to Athens, only received chaplets of leaves ; the 
 value of which at that time was greater than of golden crowns in 
 the age of Demosthenes***. The erection of a metal statue 
 (elKcov) to a person who had deserved well of the state, was in 
 early times still more unfrequent ; after Solon, Harmodius, and 
 Aristogiton, this honour was first conferred upon Conon, as 
 having liberated his country from the intolerable yoke of the 
 Spartans**\ But in later times, this reward ceased to confer 
 
 ^■^^ See book i. ch. 9, Pollux viii. 
 144. 
 
 •'^' Isacus dc Ilagn. Ilcrcd. p. 204 ; 
 Tlicophiast. Char. 17. 
 
 *^ Dein. c. Andiot. cf. .Escliin. c. 
 
 Timarch. p. 130. 
 
 ^" Book i. ch. 5. 
 
 ^^^ TEscli. c. Ctosiph. p. 570 sqq. aud 
 particularly p. 577. 
 
 ■*" Demosth. c. Lept. p. 47iJ.
 
 CH. XVIII.] 
 
 PUBLIC REWARDS. 
 
 247 
 
 any distinction 5 Chabrias^ Iphicrates, and Timotheus received 
 crowns in honour of their services, as well as others, although it 
 was offensive to the people to ascribe their actions to them"'-^ 
 But in that age, trifling or even negative services were highly 
 celebrated, and in the time of Demetrius Phalereus this practice 
 was carried to such a pitch, that in one year they erected to him 
 360 statues, in chariots, on horseback, and on foot'*^^ 
 
 This frivolous expenditure partly owed its origin to the 
 theoricon, by which the demagogues had made the people indo- 
 lent, and had induced them to flatter their corruptors"*" and 
 partly resulted from the general decline of the state and of 
 morals, and the loss of that simplicity and honesty, which dis- 
 daining outward splendour, finds a sufiicient reward in the exer- 
 cise of virtues. Athens, from her republican constitution, 
 which would always have prevented this corruption from attain- 
 ing its utmost height, only displays a feeble shadow of what in 
 monarchies or despotisms, in which the moral state of the 
 people and the government is at a low ebb, appears on a larger 
 scale. Then are the citizens, both for the state and for them- 
 selves, covetous of titles and rank, as may be seen remarkably 
 in the eastern and western Roman empire : titles of every 
 description were created and lavishly distributed ; regulations 
 concerning rank, and the splendour of the Oriental courts, were 
 introduced into the West ; outward show and pageantry, which 
 render the mind vain and slavish, became the substitutes for 
 intrinsic excellence ; and as no claims could be advanced on the 
 ground of personal merit, all consideration was derived from the 
 favour of the ruling power. 
 
 On particular occasions, pecuniary rewards were bestowed 
 at Athens. After the return of the people from the Piraeus^ 
 
 *^^ lEsch. c. Ctesiph. p. 635. See 
 the oration nepl (rvvrd^eois^ p. 172. 
 
 '^^'^ Diog. Laert. v. To, and the pas- 
 sages there quoted by Menage. 
 
 ■'^ Comp. Nepos. Miltiad. Of these 
 and of other marks of honour the 
 learned K. E. Kcihler has treated at 
 full length in his excellent dissertation, 
 of which the title is Etwas zur Bcant- 
 
 wortnng der Frage^ gab cs bei den Allen 
 Bclohnungen des Verdienstes urn den 
 Staat, welche den Ritterorden neuerer 
 Zeit 'dhnlich waren, third book, in the 
 Dorptische Beitrage for 1814, first and 
 second half; which dissertation I have 
 not been able to make use of, as I did 
 not meet with it till after the com- 
 pletion of this work.
 
 248 PUBLIC REWARDS. [bK. II. 
 
 those who at Phyle had undertaken the restoration of the 
 democracy, received 1000 drachmas for sacrifices and sacred 
 offerings, which however did not amount to 10 drachmas 
 apiece**'. According to Isocrates 10,000 drachmas were given 
 to Pindar for his splendid praise of the Athenians, for whicli 
 the Tliebans had subjected him to a fine ; according to others 
 the reward given was the double of the fine which he had been 
 condemned to pay*^\ Lysimachus, the son of Aristides, re- 
 ceived in honour of his father, upon the proposal of Alcibiades, 
 100 minas of silver, 100 plethra of wooded land, and as much 
 unplanted land in the island of Euboea, and in addition 4 
 drachmas a day*^*, a most absurd expense for an insignificant 
 and worthless individual. With better reason they gave 3000 
 drachmas to the two daughters of this distinguished man, and 
 to the daughter of Lysimachus the privilege of being maintained 
 m the Pr^'taneum, like the victors at the Olympic contest ; and 
 other donations in money were granted to the successors of 
 Aristides down to the time of Demetrius Phalereus''^^ These 
 examples, to which many others might have been added, 
 prove that the Athenian people were not illiberal in bestowing 
 pensions. Lastly, rewards for the discovery of offenders 
 (firjvvTpa) deserve to be mentioned ; thus in Andocides"^ two 
 rewards of this kind occur, one of 10,000 and another of 1000 
 drachmas, which were both actually paid. 
 
 *^^ ^sehin. c. Ctcsiph. p. 57G. 
 
 '*^° Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 87, ed. 
 Orell. The other account is given by 
 the author of the fourth epistle of 
 iEschines, p. 669. Tzetzes and others 
 state that the fine itself was only 
 1000 drachmas. See the Fragments of 
 Pindar, p. 74 ; Heyn. Schneider's Life 
 of Pindar, p. 39, and the Life of Pindar ' set upon the heads of offenders. Cf. 
 which he has published before the ' Aristoph. Av. IO72 sqf|. 
 
 Theriaca of Nicander. 
 
 ^^^ Dem. c. Lept. 95, and Wolf's 
 note. 
 
 ■*^^ Plutarch. Aristid. 27, an obscure 
 passage, the interpretation of it how- 
 ever would lead me too far. 
 
 *33 De Myst. p. 14. Of the nature 
 of rewards were the prices Avhich were
 
 CH. XIX.] ARMS, SHIPS, AND CAVALRY. 249 
 
 Chapter XIX. 
 
 Ai'^ms, Ships, and Cavalry, provided by the State, 
 
 Although the most opulent citizens equipped themselves at 
 their own expense, there is no doubt that the Athenian state 
 was under the necessity of providing a store of arms, as well in 
 time of war as during peace, that in case of need it might be pos- 
 sible to arm not only such citizens as from poverty could not pro- 
 vide for themselves, but the resident aliens, and even the slaves. 
 That such was the practice is rendered highly probable, by the 
 circumstance that large sums were expended upon naval prepa- 
 rations in time of peace. In the Piraeus was the" marine store- 
 house, which contained sails, ropes, leather-bags for provisions, 
 oars, and other articles for the equipment of vessels ; and the 
 building of ships of war was carried on unceasingly both in peace 
 and war. Themistocles passed a law that twenty new triremes 
 should be built every year : Diodorus"*^* indeed relates this event 
 under Olymp. 75, 4 (b. c. 477), but it is probable that he, hke 
 many other historians, has on this occasion put together insti- 
 tutions of different periods, in order to introduce the circum- 
 stances which in the narration immediately follow; and that 
 Themistocles had in fact carried the law at a much earlier 
 period, viz. when he obtained the decree which directed the 
 money derived from the mines to be applied to the buildino- of 
 ships for the ^ginetan war'". We are not informed whether 
 subsequently the same number of ships was built every year; 
 but we cannot well suppose that they provided a less number ; 
 for the triremes would be faUing into decay, and there were 
 generally three or four hundred in existence. The Senate of 
 Five Hundred had to superintend the building of the triremes'^^; 
 if this was not done, the customary crown was denied them ; the 
 personal superintendence was delegated to commissioners called 
 
 *^* Diod. xi. 43. j sqq. where there is also the account of 
 
 •'^^ See my dissertation upon the ; the paymaster who ran away. The 
 
 silver-mines of Lamion. I following story of Demetrius is given 
 
 ^""^ Demosth. c. Androt. p. 5U8, 20, ' by Diod.xx.4G; Plutarch.Dcmetr. 10.
 
 250 ARMS, SHIPS, AND CAVALRY, [bK. II. 
 
 the builders of the triremes. In the time of Demosthenes the 
 building ^yas stopped for a year, the treasurer of the trireme- 
 builders having eloped with 2^ talents : from the smallness of 
 this sum it would be natural to conclude that not many triremes 
 were building at the time ; but as it is probable that the timber 
 and other necessaries had been previously laid up in store, the 
 stolen money may have been applicable only to the payment of 
 the labourers: even this sum too may have been destined only 
 to some i^articular portion of the labour : and therefore it would 
 not be safe to infer from this fact that less than twenty triremes 
 were built every year. After the time of Alexander the building 
 nearly ceased, as the supply of timber from Macedonia then 
 failed. Demetrius Pohorcetes in Olymp. 118, 2 (b.c. 307)^ pro- 
 mised the Athenians timber for 100 triremes, a proof that there 
 was a scarcity of it at x-Vthens. 
 
 Another part of the military force for which Athens incurred 
 some expense in time of peace, was the cavalry. This was 
 maintained partly on account of the sumptuous appearance 
 which from the beauty of the riders and horses and the magnifi- 
 cence of their trappings it produced at processions; and partly 
 because the Athenians were well aware that if both men and 
 horses had not gone through previous training, they were 
 unserviceable in war. The particular superintendence of this 
 body belonged to the Senate of Five Hundred, who also exa- 
 mined the horses and riders"*^'; the rich were bound by law to 
 serve in it. The pay of the cavalry in time of peace was called 
 catastasis''^^, by which name the examination of the horsemen 
 made by the senate is also stated to have been called; probably 
 because the distribution of the pay and the examinations were 
 connected with one another; it was however a regular pay, and 
 not an extraordinary donative, as Reiske supposed. In the 
 speech of Lysias for Mantitheus it is mentioned, that the 
 horsemen who had served during the anarchy, were compelled 
 
 *^' Xenoph. de Re Equestri, 1, 8; poc Said. Phot, in v. Karacrracrty, Lex. 
 
 CEcon. 9, 15, and in the Hipparchus. 
 Also Lycurgns ap. Ilarpocrat. in v. 
 
 ^^" Lys. pro Mautith. p. 074; Uar- 
 
 Seg. p. 270. Reiske's erroi- in his 
 note upon Lysias had been already 
 conected by Larchcr MJni. dc TAcad. 
 des luscript. toin. xlviii. p. 02.
 
 CH. XIX.] PROVIDED BY THE STATE. 251 
 
 after the restoration of the democracy to refund the money 
 which they had received during that time : hence the gramma- 
 rians by a false generahzation of a particular case have inferred, 
 that if the state dismissed the cavalry and appointed others, it 
 required them to refund their pay to the phylarchs*^^ But the 
 state would probably have preferred giving none at all. The 
 truth is, that this measure was effected by a special decree, and 
 only on that single occasion, as the knights had been the chief 
 attendants of the thirty tyrants, and had incurred the public 
 hatred to such a degree, that to have been a knight under the 
 thirty tyrants was reckoned a disgrace. The expense of the 
 cavalry in time of peace amounted, according to Xenophon^""*, to 
 40 talents; which agrees with the Choiseul Inscription, in which 
 it is stated that there were paid out of the public treasure in 
 four prytaneias, 16 talents 2148 drachmas 3|- oboli, viz. in the 
 first 3 talents 3328 drachmas Si oboli, in the third 5 talents 
 4820 drachmas, in the fourth 3 talents, in the seventh 4 talents; 
 the rest of the pay appears to have been defrayed out of the 
 current revenue. The object of these payments was to supply 
 the provender of the horses; Ulpian expressly says that pay 
 was given for the keep of the horses""^, and in the above-men- 
 tioned inscription this money is accounted for under the name 
 of provender for the horses {alros lttttols). The amount which 
 each person received out of this grant has been differently 
 determined by modern wTiters, according as they assumed 1000 
 or 1200 as the number of knights at Athens"^ In the latter 
 case it has been calculated that they received 16 drachmas a 
 month or about 3 oboli a day, in the former, 20 drachmas a 
 month or about 4 oboli a day. Both estimates appear to be 
 too low; for even the sailors who were paid in time of peace 
 received 4 oboli a day, while the knights w^ere not only obhged 
 to keep a servant, but also two horses. The provision of a 
 horseman in war cost the Athenians a drachma a day**^ 
 
 439 pioperly it was collected by the 
 dcmarchs ; vid. ad Inscript. 80, ed. 
 Boeckh. 
 
 *^" llipparcli. i. 19. 
 
 ■*^i Ad Demostli.c. Timocrat.p. 400. 
 
 ^^^ Petit Leg. Att. viii. 1, 2; Bar- 
 thel. Anacliars. T. H. p. 184; Larcher 
 ut Slip. p. 1)2. See Jiiscript. No. 147. 
 
 '" See book ii. c. 22.
 
 252 ARMS, SHIPS, AND CAVALRY. [bK. II. 
 
 Doubtless the same sum was allowed in peace, and the only 
 difference was, that in war they received provision-money in 
 addition to their pay. This view is confirmed by the fact that 
 the catastasis (which was in truth nothing more than the 
 knights' allowance for provision in time of peace, and which 
 they were forced after the anarchy to refund) amounted to a 
 drachma. I state this solely upon the authority of an inscrip- 
 tion, with respect to which however I entertain no doubt that it 
 refers to and establishes this fact. It thus appears to me pro- 
 bable, that the whole cavalry did not receive pay in time of 
 peace, but only about 600; and for a time Athens had not more 
 than this number. Now the pay of these, reckoning the year 
 at 360 days, as Xenophon does in another place, would exactly 
 amount to 36 talents for that time. Xenophon too only says 
 that the state paid annually to the cavalry nearly 40 talents; 
 nor can the payments made out of the public treasure, according 
 to the above-quoted inscription (which are moreover unequal in 
 different prytaneias) be adduced against my hypothesis, for they 
 were contributions which might in part have been paid for 
 arrears of preceding prytaneias. Lastly, Barthelemy"*^ asserts 
 that the knights frequently kept their own horses, an error into 
 which he is led by referring to the pubhc cavalry a passage 
 which relates only to those citizens, who expended money upon 
 horses either from fondness of the animal, or in order to contend 
 for the prize at the public games. 
 
 Chapter XX. 
 
 Apj)roximate Estimate of the Ordinary Expenditure, Of the 
 Extraordinary Expenses in general. 
 
 These expenses when taken together, if the lowest estimate be 
 made of each item, did not amount annually to less than 400 
 talents; to these however, if great works of building, extraordi- 
 nary distributions of money, and large sums for festivals were 
 added, the state might have easilv consumed 1000 talents in a 
 
 ■•" Mem, dc rAciul. dcs Inscriptions, loni. xlviii. p. 351, referring to Lycurg. 
 
 in Leocrat.
 
 CH. XX.] ESTIMATES OF EXPENDITURE. 253 
 
 year, even without carrying on war, the expenses of which are 
 unhmited. 400 talents, which are equal to about 97,500/., were 
 in ancient times at least worth three times as much as at the 
 present day, if the value of the precious metals is compared 
 with that of the common necessaries of life; with this view then 
 we may consider that the former sum is equal to triple its 
 amount, or in the currency of modern times to about 290,000/.; 
 which is in fair proportion to a population of 500,000 souls, or 
 indeed if we consider the high rate of interest, low in comparison 
 with the incomes of the inhabitants. 
 
 If, however, in consequence of war or some particular extra- 
 vagance, the amount was increased (an event which was unques- 
 tionably of no unfrequent occurrence) to 1000 talents or more, 
 and as the citizens were at such a period (as indeed at all 
 others) forced to serve the liturgies required by law, the expense 
 was evidently incommensurate with the means of the state, and 
 could not be well defrayed without oppressing the more wealthy 
 classes by property-taxes, and without the help of tributary 
 allies. Now war, it is certain, produced unusually large and 
 inevitable expenses. At the present day indeed the equipment 
 of armies costs the state immense sums of money; an expense 
 from which the Greeks were very nearly exempt; for every 
 citizen carried with him clothes and arms into the field, which 
 indeed may be considered as a tax levied in another form; the 
 mercenaries also came completely armed; sometimes perhaps 
 it happened that poor citizens, foreign settlers, or slaves, were 
 sent into the field, and assistance on the part of the state was 
 necessary; a point however on which we have no accurate 
 information. Another considerable expense in modern warfare 
 is caused by artillery and ammunition; but as in ancient days 
 the heavier engines of war were on account of their cumbrous- 
 ness seldom brought into the field, they in general only had to 
 provide them upon the occasion of a siege or of the defence of 
 fortified places: the expense for light darts or javelins was 
 inconsiderable. The equipment of fleets, which was necessary 
 for maritime warfare, created a separate branch of expenditure; 
 for which it was altogether impossible that such effectual provi- 
 sion could have been made during peace as to leave nothing to
 
 254 ESTIMATES OF EXPENDITURE. [bK. II. 
 
 be provided at the breaking out of war. Lastly, the infantry 
 and cavalry, together with the persons attending upon them, 
 and the crews of the different ships, were to be supplied with 
 pay and provisions: and if the total expense of providing for 
 these services should appear to be less than would be necessary 
 in the times in which we live, it must be remembered that 
 though the Greeks maintained no standing army, and the funds 
 for the pay and provision of their troops were required only 
 for a short time, yet on the other hand the soldiers were not 
 only better paid, but also that during the most flourishing periods 
 of Athens war was almost incessant. 
 
 In order to enable the reader to take a general survey of 
 these subjects, I will treat of them separately, after having in 
 the first instance acquired some general knowledge of the mag- 
 nitude of the military force of Athens. 
 
 Chapter XXI. 
 Military Force of Athens, 
 
 Although the numbers of which the armies consisted were in 
 ancient Greece very different, according to circumstances and 
 the necessities of the occasion, and although to state any one 
 precise number of men is less possible than in the case of 
 European nations, yet it can be safely asserted that no modern 
 state, even up to the latest times in which the greatest armies 
 have been sent into the field, maintained so large a regular force 
 in proportion to its population, as was supported by Athens. 
 And it is equally true that her military force was not only on a 
 par with that of all the other states of Greece, but with the 
 exception of Sparta, it was superior to them. What Demosthe- 
 nes""'^ says of Athens at the period at which he is speaking, that 
 of all the Grecian states it had the most numerous naval force, 
 heavy-armed infantry and cavalry, and the greatest quantity of 
 money, must have held good in a higher degree when the 
 strength of Athens had not been broken^ except that Sparta 
 
 Pliilipii. i. p. 51, 20.
 
 CM. XXI.] 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 255 
 
 could send into the field a more numerous land force. Upon 
 the irruptions into Attica at the beginning of the Peloponnesian 
 war. the Peloponnesian and Boeotian forces, which were then 
 assembled there, amounted in heavy-armed soldiers alone to 
 60,000 men"'*", and consequently the whole army was more than 
 double this number. We meet indeed with far more numerous 
 armies in the Grecian states of Sicily and Italy. According to 
 Diodorus, 300,000 Sybarites contended with 100,000 inhabitants 
 of Crotona; Philistus stated the military force of Dionysius at 
 100,000 foot, 10,000 horse, and 400 ships of war, which required 
 an equipment of 80,000 men. The first of these accounts is an 
 evident exaggeration; but whether the latter is possible, I leave 
 to others to decide. Hume*''^ has already exposed the exagge- 
 rations in numbers committed by the ancients, and on the 
 whole, not without success, though he may have erred in parti- 
 cular points. 
 
 It is not enough to know that Athens had about 20,000 
 citizens who were bound to serve in war: were we to estimate 
 its military strength merely from this datum, we should form a 
 very incorrect judgment. The safest way to arrive at a satisfac- 
 tory result is, without pretending to a complete enumeration, to 
 collect the principal accounts of the land and sea forces at the 
 different periods. 
 
 First, it is needless to speak of the Trojan war, at which the 
 Athenians appeared with 50, or according to another report, 
 with 60 ships'*''^: a somewhat more certain account may, how- 
 ever, be given of the times of Solon. Before the constitution 
 of Cleisthenes, Athens had 12 phratrias, and in each of them 4 
 naucrarias or naucarias, which, as public corporations, were 
 originally the same that the demi were afterwards; they must 
 indeed have been in existence before the time of Solon, as the 
 presidents of the naucrari {7rpvTdv€i<; tcov vav/cpdpcov) are men- 
 tioned before the period of his legislation''*^ and probably all 
 
 "^^ Plutarch. Pericl. 33. 
 
 '''*'' Essay upon tlie Populousness of 
 Ancient Nations, vol. ii. p. 230, Lond. 
 17C0. 
 
 ^^8 II. B. 500, Eurip. Ipliij?. Aul. 24?." 
 
 See Grsec. Tiagoed. Princip. p. 238. 
 
 •*^^ Herod, v. 71« Instead of these 
 Thucydides (1. 12G) mentions the nine 
 arclions, who probably wore at the 
 head of the prytaneias.
 
 256 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 that Aristotle'"' means when he ascribes their institution to 
 Solon is, that the existence of their office was confirmed by that 
 lawgiver. Now each naucraria furnished 2 horsemen, amount- 
 ing altogether to 9G, and 1 vessel, making therefore in all 48, and 
 the whole military system, in respect to defraying the expenses, 
 was doubtless regulated according to naucrarias'*'. When Cle- 
 isthenes afterw^ards introduced the demi, the naucrarias were 
 still retained, probably for financial and mihtary purposes; but 
 he so far altered their constitution, that he created 50 naucra- 
 rias, 5 in each tribe''^% and consequently they now furnished 
 100 horsemen and 50 ships. This is perfectly consonant with 
 the fact mentioned by Herodotus"", that the Athenians in the 
 war against the ^Eginetans, anterior to the Persian war, could 
 only send out 50 ships of their own, and received 20 ships from 
 the Corinthians in order to increase their force; and we may 
 oljserve that in this case triremes and not smaller vessels are 
 meant, as is proved by their connexion with the Corinthian 
 ships, the Corinthians being the first who had triremes. 
 
 Miltiades after the battle of Marathon undertook the expe- 
 dition against Paros with 70 ships''^^ But it was precisely at 
 this time that Themistocles increased the naval force, and 
 brought it to the height at which we find it in the Persian war, 
 after the battles of Artemisium and Salamis. In the former 
 action 271 triremes were engaged, among which there were 127 
 belonging to Athens, which were in part manned with Platseans, 
 they having no ships of their own: besides these, the Athenians 
 gave 20 to the Chalcideans'". To these were added 53 other 
 Athenian vessels, so that Athens numbered 200 vessels among 
 those engaged at Salamis, although the whole Grecian fleet pre- 
 sent at that battle only amounted to 378 triremes*"^ Demos- 
 
 *^^ Ap. Phot, in V. vavKpapia. 
 
 ^*' Pollux viii. 108, from which pas- 
 sage Zouiie ad Xenoph. ITipparch. 9, 
 :i, has drawn some eiToneous conclu- 
 sions; Ilesycli. in v. vavKXapos; Phot, 
 ut suj).; Scliol. Aristoph. Nub. 37; Am- 
 nion, in V. vavKKrfpoi ; Ilarpocrat. and 
 Suidas in v. vavKpap'ia. 
 
 ■•'^ Clcidomus ap Pliot. ut sup. 
 
 *^3 vi. 89. 
 
 ^5* Herod, vi. 132. 
 
 ^^* Herod, viii. 1. Herodotus in 
 this and in nearly every place where 
 he speaks of ships of war, means tri- 
 remes, as is shown by their being op- 
 posed to penteconters. Comp. also viiL 
 42—48. 
 
 '■'" Herod, viii. 14, 42-48. If,
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 257 
 
 thenes in the oration for the crown"" agrees exactly with these 
 statements of Herodotus, as far as the Athenians are concerned; 
 for out of 300 Grecian he reckons 200 Athenian triremes: how 
 it came to pass that in the speech upon the Symmoriee*^® only 
 100 Athenian vessels are mentioned among 300 Grecian, I am 
 unable to explain: this circumstance might indeed lead one to 
 suspect that this oration is spurious, if there was not such strong 
 internal evidence in favour of its authenticity. We may observe 
 further, that the manning of 180 triremes required 36,000 men, 
 of whom only a few were Plataeans; but as the Athenians had 
 at that time wholly deserted their country, it would not have 
 been difficult to man that number of triremes solely with citi- 
 zens, and aliens, taking both young and old, even without 
 slaves; land-forces, as such, were for the moment not in exis- 
 tence. And how numerous these were, we learn from the bat- 
 tles of Marathon and Plataese. In the first of these 10,000 
 Athenians were engaged, including of course none but hoplitse; 
 we cannot suppose that in those times there were any slaves 
 among the regular forces; and although Pausanias'*^^ asserts 
 that slaves fought for the first time in the former battle, it may 
 be inferred from his words that they were in the ranks of the 
 Plataeans; so that as far as Athens is concerned, his testimony 
 does not apply. Athens could not then have raised a larger 
 number of troops, otherwise it would have done so at a time of 
 the greatest necessity: for probably only the three superior 
 classes were hoplitse, and the thetes were light-armed: subse- 
 quently the thetes were employed as hoplitse, although this is 
 pointed out as an uncommon event in the times of the Pelo- 
 ponnesian war*^°. The Athenians had not any bowmen or 
 
 however, all the sepai-ate numbers are 
 added together, the sum is only 366 ; 
 something therefore must have been 
 lost in the text, as others have already 
 remarked. Concerning the 200 tri- 
 remes, or 180 without the Chalcidean, 
 compare also Herod, vii. 144, viii. 61, 
 Plutarch. Themistocl. II. 14. The 
 more vague passages of Isocrates 
 (Paneg. p. 79, 82, ed. Hall.) I pass 
 
 over. [See Thuc. i. 74. Transl.] 
 
 ^^' P. 306,21. 
 
 *5« P. 186, 5. 
 
 ■*^^ i. 32, 3. They appear to have 
 been runaway Boeotian slaves, who 
 lived at Plataeae. [See also x. 20, 2. 
 Transl.] 
 
 ^^^ Harpocrat. in v. ^^res-. Thucyd. 
 vi. 43.
 
 258 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. [BK. II. 
 
 cavalry in this battle'''; even the small number of horsemen 
 which should have been there according to the former regula- 
 tions, were not in a condition to appear, and the whole order of 
 knijrhts was at that time no more than a name. Attica, from 
 the nature of the country, was little suited for cavalry*''; and 
 as this species of military is powerful among undisciphned 
 masses of infantry, the aristocracy or oligarchy in ancient days 
 was generally composed of horsemen, a form of government 
 which the Athenians of all the Grecian States were most averse 
 to. Boeotia, Phocis, Locris'''^ and Thessaly, were the chief 
 countries in which the cavalry was numerous: even the Pisis- 
 tratidse had 1000 Thessalian horsemen^ which a Thessalian 
 prince had sent to support them against the Spartans"'"*; and 
 according to an ancient alliance, the Thessalian cavalry came to 
 the assistance of the Athenians before and during the Pelopon- 
 nesian war"". At Platseee the heavy-armed infantry of the 
 Greeks amounted to 38,700 men, together with 69,500 light- 
 armed troops, besides 1800 light-armed Thespians: among 
 them there were 5000 Spartans, with 35,000 light-armed Helots 
 and 5000 Lacedeemonian hoplitse, with 5000 light-armed troops; 
 the Athenians had only 8000 hoplitse, together with the same 
 number of light-armed troops, for Herodotus expressly reckons 
 upon an average one light -armed man to each hoplite, with the 
 exception only of the Spartans, of whom each one had 7 'VNdth 
 him"''. The allied Grecian army appears not to have had any 
 cavalry, as the equestrian nations were on the side of the Per- 
 sians; but the Athenians at this battle had bowmen for the first 
 time on land"'^, who were doubtless citizens belonging to the 
 light-armed troops, and of the class of thetes; by sea more than 
 700 bowmen had already been employed at the battle of Sala- 
 
 Ilerod. vi. 112. I ciilty caunot be solved. I pass over 
 
 the accoxints of Diodorus and Pausa- 
 nias, which cannot have much weight. 
 Plutarch (Aristid. 11) agrees in the 
 number of the Athenian hoplitse. 
 *'"' Ilerod. ix. 28 sqq. cf. Gl. In the ^^r Herod, ix. GO, cf. 22. Concern- 
 number of the light-armed troops ing the bowmen in the battle of Sala- 
 Herodotus reckons 800 more than mis see Plutarch. Themistocl. 14. 
 results from liis own data : tlii.s diffi- 
 
 461 
 
 *^^ Herod, ix. 13. 
 
 ^" Thuc. ii. 9. 
 
 "^-^ Herod, v. 63. 
 
 ^" Thuc. i. 102, 107, ii. 22.
 
 CH. XXle] MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 259 
 
 mis. The Athenians would without doubt have had more 
 troops for the battle of Plataeae, if they had not at the same time 
 been compelled to furnish crews for the fleet which was engaged 
 at Mycale, and consisted, according to Herodotus, of 110, 
 according to Diodorus^ of 250 triremes^ under the command of 
 Leotychides, and on the side of the Athenians, Xanthippus*^*. 
 
 In the next age the Athenian force remained nearly the 
 same : Cimon commanded 200 Athenian and 100 allied triremes, 
 according to one account; but according to the more credible 
 statement of Thucydides,both taken together amounted to 200 tri- 
 remes: by land they were not stronger than before. In the battle 
 of Tanagra (Olymp. 80, 3, b.c. 458), the whole Athenian land 
 forces were present, excepting what were at that time in Egypt ; 
 1000 Argives were on their side, together with other allies, and yet 
 altogether they made up only 14,000 men''^^ that is, exclusively 
 of the light-armed troops, which were usually not taken into the 
 account. At the same time there was a fleet of 50 ships cruising 
 against the Spartans at sea, which likewise required 10,000 men. 
 
 The Athenians endeavoured at all times to improve and to 
 increase both the land and sea forces. It is stated by Ando- 
 cides, and also ^schines in a most obscure passage"'" (from 
 which, however, after the errors have been corrrected, some 
 truth may be extracted), that in thirteen years preceding the 
 ^ginetan war (from the 77th to the 80th Olympiad, b.c. 472 — 
 60), 100 new ships were added to the 200 which before existed; 
 besides which they had formed a regiment of 300 horsemen, 
 and had purchased the first Scythian bowmen, to the number 
 of 300. During the armistice, which was shortly afterguards 
 concluded with Sparta, in Olymp. 83, 3 (b.c. 436), and which 
 was observed up to the time of the Peloponnesian war, the 
 Athenians again made great exertions in the building of ships, 
 so that in Olymp. 87, 2 (b.c. 431), they were enabled to decree 
 that 100 new triremes should be reserved for particular pur- 
 poses*"'; the cavalry was also raised to 1200, and the same 
 
 *^^ Herod, viii. 131, Diod. xi. 34. cides de Pace. 
 
 -•^^ Time. i. 107; Diod. xi. 80. *'^ See below, chap. 23. It was 
 
 "70 Msch. de Fals. Leg. p. 334—337, : this that floated in the mind of the 
 taken from the beginning of Ando- | orator. 
 
 S 2
 
 260 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. [bK. II. 
 
 number of bowmen appointed*'' Also after the peace of Ni- 
 cias (Olymp. 89, S, B.C. 422), JEschines states that they pro- 
 cured 300, or, according to Andocides, 400 triremes. The esti- 
 mate of Pericles at the breaking out of the Peloponnesian war 
 agrees sufficiently well with the principal statements which 
 hare been here quoted'^^ According to his account, Athens 
 had not at that time more than 13,000 heavy -armed men fit for 
 active service; besides these, 16,000 of the oldest and youngest 
 of the citizens, and as many of the resident ahens as were 
 heavy-armed, were appointed to defend the fortifications of the 
 city; to which must be added 1200 cavalry, including the 
 mounted bowmen, 1600 bowmen who served on foot, and 300 
 triremes ready to put to sea; and, according to Xenophon*^*, 
 there were in harbour and on service altogether 400. Isocrates, 
 with the amplification of an orator, gives the numbers at double 
 the amount stated by all the other writers. 
 
 If we reckon that 300 triremes were manned with 60,000 
 men, the sum total of the crews does not amount to less than 
 91,800 men, — a number incredibly great for a population of 
 500,000 souls, nearly four-fifths of which were slaves. It might 
 indeed be said that Athens was not able to man 300 triremes, if 
 all the hoplitee were deducted; but even if about 10,000 hop- 
 litce are reckoned as included in the ships^ companies, the 
 number which remains is still very considerable. This fact 
 may however be accounted for by the following considerations. 
 
 The number of hoplitse is larger than we find in the accounts 
 of earlier times, as persons of greater or less age were included, 
 who only served on garrison duty and not in the field; and it was 
 farther increased by the addition of some resident aliens. All 
 indeed were regularly armed; but the whole together was not 
 
 "*7^ See above, chap. 11. Piraeus were calculated for 400, as 
 
 *7^ Thuc. ii. 13. The inaccurate j Strabo mentions in the ninth book, 
 
 Diodonis (xii. 40.) disagrees in some adding at the same time that the Athe- 
 
 points, and is not so explicit as Thu- nians had sent out that number. Whe- 
 
 cydides. ; ther the 400 trierarchs who were for- 
 
 ■•7* Cyr. Exped. vii. 1, 27. Isocrat. merly appointed every year refer to this 
 
 Panegyr. p. 85. With regard to the circumstance may be questioned. See 
 
 number 300 compare Aristopli. Acharn. book iv. ch. 12. 
 544. The places for the ships in the
 
 CH. XXI.] MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 261 
 
 essentially unlike the rising in mass of a population on the 
 alarm of invasion: and it comprised every individual capable of 
 bearing arms, from eighteen to sixty years of age. The resident 
 ahens were originally, when armed as hoplitee, only used as 
 garrison soldiers; in later times they also served in campaigns, 
 to which even ahens not domiciliated were occasionally sum- 
 moned'''^ but they were prohibited from serving in the 
 cavalry*^^ ; nor could there have been many among the hoplitae ; 
 for several Athenian demi supplied a large number of these. 
 Acharnse (by which we are not to understand the little village 
 of the charcoal-burners, as is generally supposed, but a more 
 considerable town which was celebrated for the heroism of its 
 sturdy inhabitants) ^^^ alone supplied 3000'"'^; consequently a 
 greater number of aliens could be spared for the fleet; for this 
 class of persons was probably more numerous in Attica at the 
 time of Pericles than in that of Demetrius Phalereus; and it 
 is well known that they chiefly served in the fleet^^^ In addi- 
 tion to these, the state also took into its service the out-dwellers 
 (ol %«/3fc9 oLKovvTe^;) as they were called, by whom we must 
 either understand with the grammarians, freedmen, or else 
 persons, who, though still slaves, lived apart from their masters, 
 and supported themselves by their own labour*^". If it is 
 borne in mind that the Spartans brought their Helots with 
 them into the field, that the Thessahan mounted penestee were 
 bondsmen, that a considerable number of slaves was always 
 employed in war as attendants on their masters, who were 
 sometimes even manumitted*^', that slaves are said to have 
 fought as early as at the battle of Marathon, and afterwards at 
 
 ^"'^ Thuc. iv. 90. ' Rep. Atli. i. 12; Demosth. Philipp. i. 
 
 "76 Xenoph. de Vectig. 2, 2, 5 ; cf. p. 50, 22, and others. 
 Hipparch. 9, 6. That the resident ; ^" Demosth. ut sup. and Hier. Wolf's 
 aliens frequently went into the field is note, but more particularly Harpocrat. 
 also observed by Ammonius in v. tVo- Suid. and Photius in v. tovs X"P''^ 
 TfXTyy, and I have remarked various oiKoOi/T-as', Lex. Seg. p. 316. The author 
 passages in diiferent authors to the of the speech against Euergus and 
 same purpose. Mnesibulus, p. 1161, 15, says of a 
 
 *77 Pmdar Nem.'ii. 16. j freedman, X'^P'-^ cok^i.. 
 
 *78 Thuc. ii. 20. " ! "^^ See book i. ch. 13. 
 
 ^79 Thuc. i. 143, iii. 16; Xenoph. de '
 
 262 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 Cheeronea when the Athenians granted them their liberty'"', it 
 cannot excite any surprise that a large proportion of the rowers 
 were slaves. It is remarked as an unusual circumstance, that 
 tlie seamen of the Paralos were all freemen'"'. At the successful 
 sea-fight of Arginusae there were many slaves in the Athenian 
 ileet'"'; and it equally redounds to the honour of both parties, 
 on the one hand that victory was chiefly owing to the slaves, 
 and on the other that the Athenians immediately emancipated 
 them, and made them Plateean citizens'"^ This must have 
 taken place at an earlier period of the Peloponnesian war; for 
 according to Hellanicus, who could not have been alive at the 
 time of this action, slaves that had been engaged in sea-fights 
 were made Platseans'"^ A large number of slaves was con- 
 sidered not as useful only, but as necessary to a state which 
 possessed a naval force^". The Athenians also employed many 
 foreign seamen who served for hire, and who remained as long 
 as they pleased, so that if the enemy offered better pay they 
 immediately changed sides. Thus the Athenians were able to man 
 far more ships than appears to have been possible if we merely 
 judge from the numbers of the free population. It was only on 
 some pressing emergency that citizens were employed as 
 rowers; except indeed in the sacred triremes, in which the 
 rowers were generally thetes; knights were however so em- 
 ployed on rare occasions, and at times even pentacosiomedimni. 
 Lastly, they sometimes pressed sailors in the countries of the 
 
 ^82 Dio Chrysost. xv. 
 
 *^^ Thuc. viii. 73. 
 
 *^' Xenopli. Hell. i. C, 17. 
 
 *^^ Scliol. Arlstoph. Ran. 33, cf. 193. 
 A clearer reference to it is made by 
 Aristophanes himself, ibid. 706. This 
 play was produced in tlie year (Olymp. 
 93, 3, B.C. 400) in which the battle was 
 fought, but later in the year, in the 
 month Gamelion. Concerning the fact 
 comp. also Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 6. 
 Diodorus expresses himself inaccu- 
 rately xiii. 97. 
 
 ^^^ Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 706. tovs 
 cyuunvfia^ritTnuTas 8ov\ovs 'EXXuvikos 
 
 (prjcTLV iXevOepatOrfvai Koi eyypa<p€VTas 
 Q)? nXaraifts- (rv[j.7roXiT€V€cr6ai. Sturz 
 (Fragment. Hellan. p. 119) has wholly 
 misunderstood this passage, as he was 
 not aware that Plat£eans were a kind 
 of Athenian citizens. The Plataean 
 rights of citizenship were first intro- 
 duced at Athens in Olymp. 88. 1 (b.c. 
 427), consequently this occurrence 
 cannot be placed earlier, nor can it by 
 any means be referred with Sturz to 
 the battle of Salamis. 
 
 *^^ Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 42 ; de 
 Rep. Atheu. i. 11.
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 263 
 
 allies^ and made compulsory levies of troops, as for instance 
 before the battle of Arginusse, and for the Sicilian expedi- 
 tion^^^; and this even in the subject states, although they had 
 long redeemed their obligation to serve in war^^^. Upon the 
 whole, then, it would be assuming too much, if we reckoned, 
 according to the usual computation, a serv^ant for each hoplite 
 over and above the ship^s company; there can be no doubt that 
 we must consider those who served at sea in the capacity of 
 rowers, as analogous to the servants who attended the heavy- 
 armed soldiers by land. 
 
 The cavalry was composed of the order of knights, but as a 
 military force it at first increased slowly; the numbers of 100 
 and 300 I have already quoted: afterwards, according to the 
 Scholiast on Aristophanes and Suidas"®", the number amounted 
 to 600, and last of all there were 1200 knights at Athens, 
 according to the statements of Thucydides and ^schines. The 
 ratio of the cavalry to the infantry w^as among the Greeks as 
 1 to 10, and 1200 horsemen are consequently nearly in this 
 ratio to 13,000 hoplitae; but were all the 1200 composed of 
 Athenians, and of the order of knights ? That this order might 
 have contained 1200 persons no one will deny; and even if it 
 contained fewer, there might have been that number of horse- 
 men, for probably there were many pentacosiomedimni among 
 them. But Aristophanes reckons only 1000 knights^^', and 
 this too in the comedy called by their name, which was pro- 
 duced in Olymp. 88, 4 (b.c. 424); the same number w^as given 
 by Philochorus in the fourth book of the Atthis''', who did not 
 however omit to mention that their number occasionally varied; 
 Demosthenes states the very same number^^^; and Xenophon 
 proposes, in order to bring the cavalry more rapidly and easily 
 
 Xenoph. Hell. i. 6, 18; Thuc. vi. 
 
 43. 
 
 "«» Thuc. i. 99; Plutarch. Cim. 11. 
 This had been brought about by the 
 management of Cimon himself. 
 
 ^9" Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 624, and 
 thence Suidas in v. iTnrels. Diod. xiii. 
 72, cannot be referred to this with 
 safety, as there may be auxiliary troops 
 
 among his 1200 Athenian cavalry, for 
 instance ThessaHans. The passage of 
 Harpocration quoted by Zeune ad 
 Xenoph. Hipparch. 9, 3, has nothing to 
 do with this point. 
 
 ^^' Eq. 225. 
 
 ■^^^ Ap. Hesych. in v. Itttttjs. 
 
 ^^^ De Symmor. p. 181, 17.
 
 264 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 to 1000 men, which he evidently considers as the usual 
 number, that 200 foreign horse soldiers should be main- 
 tained'"'. Larcher*'" very properly rejects the supposition of 
 Petit''% that the ancient writers had made use of 1000 as a 
 round number, upon the ground that 1200 would have equally 
 suited their purpose; and he supposes that the origin of the 
 diiference in the statements was, that from the beginning of the 
 Peloponnesian war, until the date of the Knights of Aristo- 
 phanes, they had been diminished about 200; which supposi- 
 tion appears to be untenable. My opinion coincides rather 
 with Schneider^s"*^", that in the 1200 the mounted bowmen are 
 included, as Thucydides expressly states; it is possible that 
 besides these bowmen there were 1000, viz., 100 from each 
 tribe, who were Athenians, and armed in the Greek mannner; 
 while the 200 mounted bowmen were doubtless Scythians, like 
 those who served in the infantry, and with reference to the 
 cavalr)' must be regarded as light-armed. In this capacity they 
 rode in front, even before the hipparch'^^; and in an oration 
 attributed to Lysias, it is considered degrading to an Athenian 
 to serv^e in the cavalry among the bowmen'^^ It is no objection 
 to the above hypothesis, that Xenophon not only makes no 
 mention of the existence of the foreign cavalry at Athens, but 
 himself first proposes that such a body should be formed; for 
 these bowmen, being light-armed soldiers, did not come into 
 consideration when he was treating of the maintenance or 
 improvement of the cavalry, which was composed of citizens. 
 
 Thucydides mentions 1600 bowmen who served on foot, the 
 orators only 1200; this difference also may probably be ac- 
 counted for by the fact that the mercenary Scythian bowmen 
 were at most 1200*^% but that the others were either citizens of 
 the poorer classes, or resident aliens, who were light-armed, and 
 
 *^* Hipparch. ut sup. 
 
 *^^ In his otherwise superficial Me- 
 moir on the Class of Knights in Greece, 
 M^m. de I'Aead. des Inscript. torn, 
 xlviii. p. 92. 
 
 "" Leg. Att. viii. 1,2. 
 
 *'7 Ad Xenoph. Hipparch, ut sup. 
 
 •'^^ Xenoph. Socrat. Mem. iii. 3, 1. 
 
 ^^^ Lys. c. Alcib. XftTToral, ii.p. 565. 
 This passage is decisive, although the 
 speech is probably not the work of 
 Lysias, but of some other contempo- 
 rary. 
 
 ''' See book ii. ch. 11.
 
 CH. XXI.j 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 265 
 
 chiefly trained in shooting. Bowmen were present in the 
 battles of Salamis and Platseae, before any Scythians had been 
 procured; and it may be distinctly seen from an inscription 
 still extant, that a difference was made between foreign bowmen 
 and those who were citizens {^eviKol and aariKoiy: finally, the 
 bowmen, who occur in two Athenian military lists'*^ ^, appear to 
 have been citizens, especially as in one immediately after 
 the bowmen a new division begins with the superscription 
 "foreigners'^ (feVot). The Athenians also had sometimes 
 Cretan bowmen in pay, as Thucydides and Pausanias mention. 
 The accounts of the mihtary force which was in action during 
 the Peloponnesian war appear to coincide with the numbers 
 here ascertained; and of this I will now adduce some examples. 
 At the very beginning of the war, Pericles sent 100 ships to the 
 Peloponnese, to which 50 Corcyreean and other allied ships 
 were added; at the same time 30 vessels were sent to Locris, 
 and some must without doubt have been reserved for the 
 defence of Attica itself ^°^ So again, in the second year of the 
 war, while the enemy's troops were in the country, Pericles 
 went to Epidaurus with 100 Athenian and 50 Lesbian and 
 Chian triremes, having on board 4000 hoplitee and 300 horse- 
 men. In the fourth year of the same war, the Lesbians having 
 revolted, 40 triremes were sent against them ; at the same time 
 30 were sent to the Peloponnese, and 100 others were equipped 
 in order to protect Attica from invasion; these were manned 
 with Athenians, who were however neither knights nor penteco- 
 siomedimni, and with resident aliens^°^ At the end of the 
 summer 1000 hoplitse were sent to Lesbos, who themselves 
 rowed the ships thither'"*. Thucydides remarks, that at that 
 time the number of ships in use was very large, but that it was 
 still greater at the beginning of the war, when Attica, Salamis, 
 
 ' Corp. Inscript. No. 80. 
 
 s"! Corp. Inscript. Nos. 165 and 171. 
 [In his remarks on the latter inscrip- 
 tion, vol. i. p. 305— 6, the author re- 
 tracts the opinion expressed in the 
 text, that the bowmen mentioned in 
 these two inscriptions were Athenian 
 
 citizens, and states his reasons for con- 
 sidering them to be foreigners. — 
 Transl.] The passage of Pausanias 
 i. 29, 5, refers to the Cretan bowmen. 
 
 5"^ Thuc. ii. 24—26. 
 
 503 Thuc. ii. 56, iii. 3, 7, 16- 
 
 5«^ Thuc. iii. 18.
 
 266 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 and Euboea, were guarded by 100 ships, 100 had been de- 
 spatched to the Peloponnese, and 50 more to Potidsea and to 
 other places, amounting altogether to 250 ; besides these there 
 were 4600 hoplitcE before the walls of Potideea (only 1600 how- 
 ever for some time), and an equal number of attendants*''\ 
 Thus we find in this instance, in addition to the land forces 
 that remained in Attica, a body of 60,000 men in service. In 
 the expedition to Sicily the numbers were not inferior^*'^ Al- 
 though the war was continued in Greece, the Athenians decreed 
 that 60 ships should be sent to Sicily, under the command of 
 Nicias and Alcibiades; but Nicias, rightly estimating the mag- 
 nitude of the enterprise, saw that it would be necessary to have 
 land troops in addition to a powerful naval armament, and 
 counselled them to send a large number of hoplitee, bowmen, 
 and slingers, both of their own and of the allies, together with 
 provision ships and apparatus for baking. He disapproved 
 however of the war altogether; but in consequence of his 
 advice the people sent 60 swift-sailing triremes with 40 military 
 transports, to which were also added 34 allied triremes and the 
 provision ships: the hoplitee were 5100 in number, of whom 
 700 were thetes created for the occasion, and 1500 Athenians 
 from the list of citizens; the others were mostly subject allies 
 and a few mercenaries ; also 480 bowmen, of whom 80 were 
 Cretans, 700 Rhodian slingers, 120 light-armed Megarian exiles, 
 and 30 horsemen. If we reckon the crews of 134 triremes, 
 each at 200 men, and the attendants of the hoplitae and cavalry, 
 we find that they amounted to 38,560 men: 250 dismounted 
 horse soldiers followed at a later period, who were to have been 
 mounted in Sicily, and also 30 mounted bowmen^". And yet 
 they were able at the same time to send 30 ships to the Pelo- 
 ponnese*"^, and other small fleets were dispersed about in 
 various places. Nor was this all; for 10 ships were sent as a 
 reinforcement under Eurymedon to Sicily, and 20 for the 
 blockade of the Peloponnese ; where soon afterwards 30 more 
 
 *«* Thuc. iii. 17. 
 
 '»« Time. vi. 8, 21, 22, 31 s<i<i. 43. 
 
 ''' Time, 
 cib. 20. 
 ''^ Thuc. 
 
 vi. 94: cf. riutarcli. Al- 
 
 vi. 105,
 
 CH. XXI.] MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 26/ 
 
 were sent under the joint command of Charicles and Demos- 
 thenesj with 60 Athenian and 5 Chian vessels, together with 
 1200 hophtee from the Hst of the citizens, and others from the 
 islands ; the Thracian peltasts, who arrived too late, were sent 
 home again on account of the scarcity of pay; fresh troops 
 however were received in different places ; other ships were 
 also provided, but some of them were again dismissed. When 
 Demosthenes and Eurymedon arrived in Sicily they had 73 
 triremes, 5000 hoplitee, together with a number of Grecian and 
 Barbarian javelineers, sHngers, and bowmen^*'^ Now if we add 
 together the whole number of men of all descriptions who went, 
 after the departure of the first fleet, to Sicily, viz., cavalry, hop- 
 litee, light-armed soldiers, and ships' crews, together with the 
 servants of the cavalry and hoplitse, it gives about 26,000 men ; 
 so that the whole military force which was sent to Sicily 
 amounted to about 64,000 men. In this, moreover, the Sicilian 
 auxiliaries are not included, but only the Grecian and Italian. 
 But in the decisive sea-fight at Syracuse only 110 ships were 
 engaged, and some of these were in very bad condition*^"; 
 40,000 men survived the battle, as Thucydides informs us" '; of 
 whom many were destroyed by land, 18,000 were put to death, 
 7000 made prisoners in a body; of the rest some were kept as 
 slaves by the soldiers, and others sold"^ Diodorus therefore 
 makes Nicolaus underrate the number, when he states the 
 Athenian forces in Sicily at more than 200 ships, and above 
 40,000 men^^^ ; he might have said above 60,000 men. 
 
 This loss was the greatest that the Athenians had ever 
 experienced ; although nearly equal reverses had been sustained 
 in earlier times. " In Egypt,'' says Isocrate&^'^, whose account 
 
 *°^ Thuc. vii. 16, 17, '20, 27,42. Dio- for exaggerating : see his Sparta, vol. 
 donis is less precise in his statements ii. p. 455. 
 
 than Thucydides ; but he agrees with ^'"* Ivp-jxax, 29. To what the loss of 
 
 him in the main. See xii. 84, xiii. 2, 7, 1<>,000 hoplitse in the Pontus refers I 
 
 8,9,11. am wholly ignorant; but hardly to 
 
 ^'" Thuc. vii. 60. the auxiliary troops of Cyrus, which 
 
 ^•' Thuc. vii. 75. had nothing to do with the Athenians. 
 
 •^'^ Diod. xiii. 20. yEiian V. H. v. 1 1, transcribes this pas- 
 
 ^^^ Diod. xiii. 21. Manso misrepre- i sage of Isocrates, but purposely omits 
 
 sents Diodorus, and then censures him | these 10,000 soldiers. The manner in
 
 268 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. [bk. II. 
 
 of the defeats of Athens, although inaccurate, is very remarkable : 
 "200 triremes were lost, with all their crew, 150 off Cyprus; 
 and in the Pontus 10,000 hoplitae of the Athenians and the 
 allies; in Sicily 40,000 men, and 240 triremes; and afterwards 
 in the Hellespont 200 more : but as to the triremes which had 
 been lost by tens and fives, and the men who had been destroyed 
 by thousands and two thousands, who could enumerate them V 
 In consequence of these calamities, the phratrias and the 
 register of the Lexiarchs were filled with aliens, in order to 
 replenish the number of the citizens ; and the races of the most 
 celebrated men and the noblest families, which had hitherto 
 preserved an unbroken descent through internal troubles and 
 disturbances, and through the vicissitudes of the Persian war, 
 were at length sacrificed to their struggles for dominion, and 
 became extinct. Perhaps no country ever adopted so many 
 strangers as Athens : hence that mixture of languages soon 
 arose, which Xenophon complains of in his Essay upon the 
 Athenian state; but whatever may have been the inconve- 
 niences resulting from thi§ practice, no other means would have 
 sufficed, after such great and repeated losses, to keep up the 
 numbers of the citizens : with regard indeed to the defeat in 
 Sicily, many strangers were involved in it ; the greater part of 
 the citizens were at home : for as at that precise period, after 
 Alcibiades had been recalled from Sicily, the Spartans occupied 
 Decelea, and kept it constantly garrisoned, it was impossible to 
 leave the city in a defenceless state. The fact of there having 
 been only 5000 hoplitee admitted into a share of the govern- 
 ment which was introduced in Olymp. 92, 1 (b.c. 412), imme- 
 diately after the Sicilian expedition^'*, may indeed in part have 
 been occasioned by the misfortunes of war, but is chiefly to be 
 accounted for from the circumstance that the thetes are not 
 comprised in this number; for by law they were prohibited 
 from serving as hoplitae ; and in this instance they would have 
 
 which Isocrates counted the 240 ships 
 has been shown by Perizonius upon 
 ^.lian. Cneius Piso justly observed 
 that the population of Athens in later 
 
 times was a conflux of vagabonds and 
 rabble, Tacit. Annal. ii. 55. 
 ''^ Thuc. viii. 97.
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 269 
 
 been still more strictly excluded, as the registration was made 
 in reference to an aristocratical constitution, in which the hop- 
 litse were to compose the pubhc assembly ; for which reason 
 many citizens, even who were not thetes, were unquestionably 
 debarred from a participation. The same holds good of the 
 3000 in the anarchy^'% who were hoplitse; but it is impossible 
 that these were the only persons of this description, and we 
 must suppose that they were selected arbitrarily from among 
 the citizens who remained at home. 
 
 By these means Athens sustained herself in the years 
 immediately following the Sicilian expedition; and notwith- 
 standing her unfavourable condition, defeated the Lacedaemonians 
 off Abydos (Olymp. 92, 2, B.C. 411), with 86 ships'^^; and soon 
 afterwards for the second time, off Cyzicus"^ Then Alcibiades 
 appeared with 100, and afterwards Conon with 70 ships'*'^; and 
 this fleet being unsuccessful, the Athenians, in Olymp. 93, 3 
 (B.C. 406), equipped 110 ships within 30 days, the crews of 
 which were composed of all persons who were able to serve in 
 war, both slaves and citizens; and there were even some knights 
 who went with them. To these were added 10 Samian and 
 more than 30 other allied vessels, and several which had been 
 detached to different places were recalled, making altogether 
 more than 150; while Conon retained 70 under his immediate 
 command, of which 30 were lost'^". The crews of the ships 
 that fought at Arginusae alone amounted to more than 30,000 
 men; those of Conon's fleet to 14,000, and many persons capa- 
 ble of bearing arms must necessarily have remained at home. 
 Lastly, in the battle of ^gospotamos the Athenian force 
 amounted to 180 triremes, which would require alone 36,000 
 men^^'. 
 
 Even after the unfortunate termination of the Peloponnesian 
 war, the Athenians soon recovered themselves, and in Olvmp. 
 
 "'^ Xenoph. Hell. ii. 3, 12, 13, 4, 2. 
 
 "^ Time. viii. 104, and Diod. xiii. 
 under Olymp. 92, 3. 
 
 *i« Xenoph. Hell. i. 1, Diod. xiii. 
 under Olymp. 92, 2. 
 
 '^^ Xenoph. Hell. i. 5, Diod. iinder 
 
 Olymp. 93, 1, 2. 
 
 5^" Xenoph. Hell. 1. 6, Diod. under 
 Olymp. 93, 3. 
 
 "' Xenoph. Hell. ii. I, 13, Diod, 
 under Olymp. 93, 4.
 
 9T 
 
 70 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 IT. 
 
 100, f (B.C. 377)j were enabled to think of equipping, according 
 to Polybius, 100 ships and 10,000 hoplitae; or according to 
 Diodorus, 200 ships, 20,000 hoplitee, and 500 cavalry''^ The 
 forces of Chares, Timotheus, Chabrias, and Iphicrates, were 
 not inconsiderable, as we learn from the historians; according 
 to Isocrates, the state possessed 200 triremes even at a later 
 period than this; Demosthenes in the 106th Olympiad (b.c. 
 354), reckons the naval force at 300 vessels, which could be 
 sent to sea on an emergency, together with 1000 horse-soldiers, 
 and as large a number of hoplitee as might be wished^"; Lycur- 
 gus provided the state with 400 triremes^^*, and so completely 
 filled the docks that they could not contain any more; the 
 Athenians sent to the assistance of the Byzantines not less than 
 120 ships, together with hoplitae and a supply of missiles*"; 
 and before the battle of Chceronea, they decreed to send 200 
 ships to sea''^^ At this time, however, the military force was 
 in a continually declining state, as the citizens were unwilling 
 to serve, and preferred carrying on war with mercenaries, while 
 they were squandering away the public revenue at home in 
 shows and banquets. It is true that mercenaries had been fre- 
 quently employed in the Peloponnesian war, both in the fleet 
 as rowers, and by land as heavy and light-armed troops; but it 
 had not then become a principle, that the whole war should 
 depend on the services of mercenaries. Isocrates^^^ at the time 
 of the Social war, complains that his countrymen no longer 
 exerted themselves; so far from it, that they employed refugees, 
 deserters, and other criminals, who would immediately turn 
 their arms against Athens if any body offered them higher pay; 
 and this the Athenians did at a time when they were hardly 
 able to defray the expenses of the administration; whereas for- 
 merly, when there was abundance of treasure in the Acropolis, 
 
 *" Diod. XV. 29, Tolyb. ii. 62, Comp. 
 book iv. ch. 4. 
 
 "' Isocrat. Areop. 1, Demosth. de 
 Symmor. p. 181, 17, p. 183, 15, p. 
 18G, 8. 
 
 '"'" See Meurs. Fort. Att. vii. and 
 more particularly the tltird decree 
 
 after the Lives of the Ten Orators. 
 
 ^'^^ Decree of the Byzantines in 
 Demosth. pro Corona, p. 25G. 
 
 ^^^ Decree in Demosth. pro Corona, 
 p. 290. 
 
 ^^' ^vfxfiax. 16.
 
 CII. XXI.] 
 
 MILITARY FORCE OF ATHENS. 
 
 271 
 
 the citizens themselves served in war. It was a common prac- 
 tice to write down 10^000, 20,000 mercenaries; but it was a 
 force which existed only on paper, and nothing more than a 
 decree to that effect went out with the general: they chose 10 
 generals, 10 taxiarchs, 10 phylarchs, and 2 hipparchs; but with 
 the exception of 1, they all remained at home, and together 
 with the sacrificers, superintended the processions. Every 
 general was two or three times put on his trial for life or 
 death, and when defeated with his mercenaries, was made the 
 object of party accusations. In order to diminish this evil, 
 Demosthenes counselled the Athenians that the fourth part of 
 the standing army which he advised them to form, should be 
 composed of citizens. In addition to this it often happened 
 that the foreign leader of the mercenaries was a general, the 
 equipments of the army were never ready at the right time, and 
 that the war was carried on upon unsound military principles'^*. 
 The greatest number of mercenaries which Athens collected at 
 this time against Philip was, according to the statement of 
 Demosthenes, 15,000, together with 2000 cavalry, which were 
 furnished by the Euboeans, Achaeans, Corinthians, Thebans, 
 Megarians, Leucadians, and Corcyrseans, in addition to the 
 other force composed of the citizens of these nations^": others 
 than these Athens was forced to maintain at her own expense. 
 
 The total numerical amount of the land army must always 
 be estimated at twice the number of men which is stated by 
 ancient authors, when they merely mention hoplitae and cavalry. 
 For each hoplite had an attendant (vTrrjpirrj^;, crKevo<ji6pos) 
 who carried his baggage and provisions, and also his shield; 
 the horseman, too, had a servant who attended to his horse 
 [liriTOKoixosy^^, This regulation diminished the labour of the 
 soldiers ; but it must necessarily have produced a regular and 
 
 5^ Demosth. Philip, i. p. 45, 47, 53. 
 
 *^^ Demosth. pro Corona, p. 306. 
 And thence Plutarch, in his Life of 
 Demosthenes, 17. The statement in 
 the first decree at the end of the Lives 
 of the Ten Orators and in /Esch. c. 
 Ctesiph. p. 488, is lower, Cf. ibid. p. 
 
 536. ^schines states a less number, 
 as he does not include the Theban 
 mercenaries. 
 
 ^3° Thuc. iii. 17, viL 75,78, Xenoph. 
 Hell. ii. 4, comp. Barthel. Anacliar. 
 vol. ii. p. 145.
 
 272 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF [bK. IT. 
 
 continual system of depredation. That the armies were also 
 attended by a large train of carriages and asses"' and of suttlers 
 does not require to be stated. 
 
 Chapter XXIL 
 
 Pay and Provisioning of the Army and Navy. 
 
 In ancient times the troops received no pay, excepting such 
 foreign soldiers as engaged themselves in the service of a 
 state; a practice which the Carians were the first to introduce, 
 and which among the Greeks the Arcadians, who resembled the 
 Swiss in their mercenary habits, were particularly prone to. 
 Pericles first introduced the pay of the citizens who served as 
 soldiers"^ 
 
 The payment was made under two different names; one 
 being the wages {ijlktOos) paid for actual service, which the sol- 
 diers, when the cost of their arms and clothes had been 
 deducted, were able to lay by; and secondly, the allowance for 
 provisions {a-cTrjpea-cov, o-LrapKeca, alro^), which were seldom 
 furnished in kind. The soldiers being free citizens, it was 
 thought that the state was bound to pay them highly, and that 
 if freemen undertook this hazardous service and discharged 
 their duties at the risk of their lives, they were entitled at least 
 to a maintenance: the generals and commanders were, however, 
 proportionally ill paid, as their distance from the common 
 soldiers was not so great as at the present day; the honour of 
 their situation was also considered as sufficient indemnification, 
 and they had the chance of being remunerated by booty and 
 contributions. The pay was generally given out in gold; by 
 the Athenians probably for the most part in their own silver ; 
 the provision-money was also given at the same time, which 
 for that reason has not always been properly distinguished by 
 ancient writers from the pay, and consequently it will be 
 
 "^^ Xenopli.(Econ. 84, and frequent- | "^ Ulpiau ad Demosth. Trepi o-vi/raf 
 ly in the Historians. | p. 50 A.
 
 CTI. XXII.J THE ARMY AND NAVY. 2^3 
 
 impossible for us always to ascertain the difference. The pay 
 of an hoplite never amounted to less than 2 oboli a day, and 
 the provision money to the same sum : which was still the 
 common rate in the age of Demosthenes ; since this orator 
 reckons 10 drachmas a month for the provision money of the 
 hoplitee, and 30 drachmas for that of the cavalry, together con- 
 sequently they amounted to 4 oboli a day for each hoplite ; 
 the attendants were not always paid separately. The life of a 
 soldier was proverbially called, on account of this rate of pay, 
 the life of a tetrobolon {rerpw^oXov ^io<;y^^. At the same 
 time higher pay was frequently given. In the beginning of the 
 Peloponnesian war, the hoplitse who besieged Potideea received 
 daily 2 drachmas a head, one for themselves, the other for their 
 servants"''; in which instance the pay was doubtless rated at 3 
 oboli, and the provision at the same sum. In the Acharneans 
 of Aristophanes"' some Thracian soldiers are introduced de- 
 manding 2 drachmas for pay, including of course the provision 
 money: the Thracians who were sent back in the Sicilian war 
 on account of a scarcity of money, were to have received a 
 drachma each day"^; this was the rate of pay for every descrip- 
 tion of force in the Sicilian expedition. If here again we reckon 
 one half for the pay, and the other for provision, each amounted 
 to 3 oboli ; and this was the sum which the bowmen at Athens, 
 who composed the city-guard, received, and as they were 
 bondsmen it was probably paid not as wages, but provision 
 money"'. Cyrus the younger at first gave a daric a month to 
 the Grecians in his service, and afterwards li"^ the former 
 pay would amount to 20, the latter to 30, drachmas of silver, 
 reckoning the ratio of gold to silver as 1 to 10, which is pro- 
 bably far too low for that age. Seuthes gave a Cyzicenic stater 
 a month to the common soldiers, twice that sum to the lochagi. 
 
 ^^ Eustath. ad Odyss. p. 1405, ad II. 
 p. 951, ed. Rom. A passage of the 
 comic poet Theopompus, where he 
 speaks of a pajment of 2 oboli, can 
 only be understood of the pay, without 
 the provision. See book i. ch. 22. 
 
 "* Thuc. iii. 17, to which Pollux 
 iv. 165, refers. 
 
 535 Vs. 158. The date of this play 
 is Olymp. 88, 3 (b.c. 426). 
 
 "6 Thuc. vii. 27. 
 
 53' Comp. above b. ii. ch. 11. 
 
 5-*« Xenoph. Cyr. Exped. i. 3, 21. 
 
 T
 
 274 
 
 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 and four times that sum to the generals"*: this same gold coin 
 is also mentioned in other places as monthly pay'"*'; the double 
 and four-fold scale for the commanders was probably the esta- 
 blished rate of payment ; thus Thimbron offered the common 
 soldiers a daric a month, and the commanders in the same pro- 
 portion as Seuthes^*'; sometimes indeed common mercenaries, 
 if they particularly distinguished themselves, received from 
 those who understood how to purchase their favour, two-fold, 
 three-fold, and four-fold pay {^LfioLpla, rpi/jLOipia, TerpajMOi- 
 pLaY*^, In these cases the provision money is included, 
 without its being particularly specified. After the destruction 
 of Mantinea, the Spartans and their allies having decreed to 
 raise an army, the allies were permitted to contribute money 
 instead of troops, at the rate of 3 ^ginetan oboli a day for each 
 foot soldier, and four times this sum for the cavalry ^''^; now 3 
 ^ginetan are 5 Athenian oboli, which were in this case evidently 
 to be given for pay and provision together. In the time of the 
 Peloponnesian war, the same sum was stipulated for provision 
 alone. For in the alliance of the Athenians, Argives, Manti- 
 neans, and Eleans, it was fixed that the state affording assist- 
 ance should provide the troops which they sent with necessaries 
 for thirty days ; and that if the troops remained longer, the 
 state to whose assistance they came should give the infantry 3 
 -iEginetan oboli a day, and the cavalry twice this sum, for pro- 
 vision (o-fcTo?)^'"'. It follows at the same time from these facts, 
 that the cavalry were treated very differently from the infantry, 
 as their pay and provision money sometimes amounted to twice 
 and even three or four times the pay received by the latter ; at 
 Athens the three-fold scale was adopted ; if the hoplitse received 
 2 oboli for provision money, the horsemen received a drachma*". 
 This latter proportion also existed among the Romans*"*^ 
 
 These examples show that during the Peloponnesian war. 
 
 "^ Xenoph. Cyr. Exped. vii. 3, 19, 
 cC viL 6, 1. 
 
 ^*^ Xenoph. ibid. v. 6, 12. 
 ^^ Xenoph. ibid. vii. 6, 1. 
 ^*^ Xenoph. Hell. vi. 1, 4. Ai^oipT- 
 
 rat is interpreted incorrectly in Lex. 
 Seg. p. 242. 
 
 ^" Xenoph. Hell. v. 2, 14. 
 
 5" Thucyd. v. 4?. 
 
 *^^ Demosth. Philipp. i. p. 47. 
 
 ^*^ Lipsius Milit. Rom. v. 16.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE ARMY AND NAVY. 275 
 
 the soldiers who served on land were the best paid ; afterwards, 
 and particularly in the time of Philip, less was given, as the 
 multitude of adventurers and mercenaries had increased, and 
 the wealthy citizens seldom served, who would have required a 
 higher pay to have enabled them to live in a manner suitable 
 to their habits. The pay of the naval forces was in like manner 
 variable ; although it does not appear to have fallen off in a 
 degree at all corresponding to that of the land service ; but it 
 was first higher, then it became lower, and then something 
 higher again. As the statements given are generally of the sum 
 total of the pay of the whole ship^s company, it will be neces- 
 sary first to ascertain the numbers of the crew of a trireme. 
 In the sea as well as in the land service a distinction was made 
 between pay and provision {acrrjpeacovy*'^; in the sea service 
 the latter was frequently given in money^^% and was supplied at 
 the public expense; although if it happened that the generals 
 had no money, the trierarch perhaps would either contribute 
 some part, or voluntarily engage the whole number of seamen 
 at his own cost^*^. Demosthenes reckons 20 minas a month as 
 the provision money of a trireme""; which, upon the supposi- 
 tion that the 200 men in a trireme were paid according to the 
 same rate, or rather that 200 times the pay of a common sailor 
 was required for the payment of the whole crew, would come to 
 2 oboli a head, the same sum that a common land soldier was 
 to receive according to the plan of Demosthenes. Now since 
 the pay and provision money used to be equal, the common 
 soldier received at that time 4 oboli for both, the sum paid to 
 the paralitse as wages in time of peace"'. On the other hand, 
 the Athenians in the beginning of the Peloponnesian war gave 
 the seamen as much as a drachma a day"*; which was the case 
 afterwards in the expedition against Sicily ; when the trierarchs 
 also made additional allowances to the thranitse, and to certain 
 
 5^7 Demosth. c. Polycl.p 1209, 12. 
 
 5^8 Orat. c. Timoth. p. 1187, 21 ; 
 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1223, 19, p. 
 1224, 1. 
 
 ^*^ The latter for example in the 
 
 case in Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1208, 15. 
 5 5" Philip, i. p. 47, 48. 
 "1 Book ii. ch. 16. 
 "2 Thuc. iii. 17. 
 
 T 2
 
 276 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF [bK. II. 
 
 other persons employed in the ship, such as the steersman, &c."' 
 If at this rate of payment we again reckon the crew at 200 
 men, the monthly pay amounted to a talent; according to 
 which the Egestseans, for the purpose of promoting the war 
 against Syracuse, sent 60 talents to Athens as monthly pay for 
 60 vessels"''. In general however the Athenians at that time 
 only gave 3 oboli, which, it clearly appears, were both for the 
 daily pay and provision of a sailor; if they gave a drachma, it 
 was for the purpose of stimulating the exertions and augmenting 
 the numbers of the men. Thus Tissaphernes promised to the 
 seamen at Sparta an Attic drachma a da)^, and at first he kept 
 his word (Olymp. 92, 1, B.C. 412), although afterwards at the 
 instigation of Alcibiades he refused to give more than 3 oboli, 
 until the king had allowed the whole drachma, as even Athens 
 only gave 3 oboli. In withholding this he was not influenced 
 by want of money; but, in addition to other reasons, he feared 
 lest the possession of so much more money than they wanted 
 should produce insubordination amongst the seamen, and lead 
 them into dissolute habits, by which their bodies would be 
 enfeebled. At the same time he consented, instead of 3 oboli a 
 day for each man, to give 3 talents a month for 5 ships, i. e. for 
 every ship 36 minas; if therefore we reckon 200 men to a 
 trireme, 18 drachmas a month or 3f oboli a day would be the 
 pay of each man"\ In the agreement between Sparta and 
 Persia the rate fixed had been only 3 oboli"% and Tissaphernes 
 gave the rest merely as a voluntary addition, and without the 
 approval of the king. Again, at a subsequent period, the 
 Spartans demanded a drachma of Cyrus the younger, and main- 
 
 *" Thuc. vi. 31, with the SchoUast. rrevre vavs nXeov dv8p\ UanTarj rpels 
 
 "^ Thuc. vi. 8. o/3oXoi a)^oXoyj7^7;o-ai/ contains the same 
 
 '^^ Thuc. viii. 45, 29. The latter sense, since Tzapa TreVre means, by every 
 
 passage Palmei-ius and Duker have five ships, and the following sentence 
 
 alone nghtly understood : the note of from kul toIs aXXois down to ediboroy 
 
 the latter is the best worth consulting, shows the justness of this correction. 
 It should evidently be written, eV yap **^ Concerning the agreement see 
 
 TTePTcuaviTpiaraXauTaedidovTov iJLTjvbs, Thuc. viii. 5. That only 3 oboli was 
 
 and the words kuI nevT^Kovra are an the sum fixed in it is evident from 
 
 imintelUgible addition from viii. 26. Xenopli. Hellen. i. 5, 3. 
 The preceding sentence op.a>s Se napa
 
 CH. XXII.] 
 
 THE ARMY AND NAVY. 
 
 277 
 
 tained their unreasonable claim by saying that the Athenian 
 sailors would desert to their side, as they only received half as 
 much 3 in answer to which Cyrus appealed to the agreement, by 
 which each ship was to receive only 30 minas a month, or 3 
 oboli for each man; however, Cyrus allowed himself to be 
 prevailed on by their entreaties to give to each sailor an addi- 
 tional obolus, after which they received 4 oboli a day"^. In 
 this instance also 200 men are reckoned to the trireme. It 
 may be farther observed that the seamen, when they were first 
 engaged, received bounties and advances of money, that they 
 generally made considerable demands, and after all were with 
 difficulty retained in the service. The travelling expenses of 
 those who went away either by land or water were frequently 
 paid, and particularly by private individuals"^. 
 
 The foregoing statements relative to the pay of the sailors, 
 concur throughout in the fact that there were 200 men to be paid 
 in each trireme : and in these accounts the marines or soldiers, 
 as well as the sailors, must have been included, since otherwise a 
 separate payment for them would have been somewhere men- 
 tioned; and they are evidently comprised among the ship^s 
 company, when the ancients speak of the pay of the seamen. 
 But as a doubt has been raised whether a trireme did in fact 
 contain so large a crew, it appears necessary to produce addi- 
 tional testimony in order to confirm our supposition. 
 
 According to Herodotus, Cleinias, the son of Alcibiades, 
 served in the battle of Salamis with a trireme of his own and 
 200 men"^ The same author^^" estimates the whole force of 
 Xerxes, which consisted of 1207 ships, at 241,400 men, taking 
 200 for each as the regular number, inclusive of the marines 
 that belonged to them ; the 30 epibatse who were also on board, 
 did not belong to the regular complement, but were added to 
 the full crew from the Persians, Medes, and Sacse. Plato in the 
 
 557 Xenoph. Hell. i. 5, 3, 4 ; Plut. 
 Lysander, 4 ; Alcib. 35. 
 
 558 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1208, 16, 
 p. 1212, 9, 19, de Trierarch. Corona, p. 
 1231, 10; Time. vi. 31; Lysias pro 
 Mautith. p. 579. 
 
 559 Herod, viii. I7. 
 
 560 Yii. 184, of. 96. Duker ad Tlmcyd. 
 viii. 29, unjustly blames Meibomius 
 (de Fabrica Triremium) for not in- 
 cluding tliese 30 epibatse in the calcu- 
 lation .
 
 278 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF [bK. II. 
 
 Critias**' gives a sketch of a military force for the inhabitants 
 of Atlantica according to the custom prevalent in his own time, 
 excepting that he speaks of military chariots, which were but 
 seldom used even in the interval between the Persian and 
 Peloponnesian wars. Of the 60,000 lots into which he divides 
 the country, each is to supply, besides the chariots and their 
 drivers, 2 hoplitse, 2 bowmen, 2 slingers, 3 light armed soldiers 
 for throwing stones, and the same number for throwing javelins, 
 and lastly, 4 seamen for the manning {ifXriptoixa) of 200 ships, 
 which gives 200 a-piece. There is however one statement 
 which does not agree with this number. In the Lexicon 
 Rhetoricum^*^^ the complement of a penteconter is stated at 50 
 men, or 1 lochus, and the trireme at 300 men, or 6 lochi. It is 
 possible that the rowers of the triremes were distributed into 6 
 lochi, each row upon either side being separately considered a 
 lochus ; but that each lochus amounted to 50 men is unques- 
 tionably false; it is more probable that the number was 25 men 
 or thereabouts, if the lochus was numerous, and that the 
 marines made up the rest of the crew. But it may be said, if 
 there were 200 men to each trireme, how could the pay of the 
 whole crew have been exactly 200 times that received by the 
 common sailor; a talent a month, when the common sailor 
 received a drachma, and a half talent when he received 3 oboli ? 
 must not the commanders and the experienced seamen have 
 received more than the common rowers ? To this I answer as 
 follows; that in the payment of a ship^s crew it was settled 
 once for all, that the pay of a trireme should be 200 times the 
 wages of a common seaman : it must at the same time be con- 
 sidered as probable, that the rowers received less than the 
 average rate of pay, and that the able seamen received some- 
 what more, so that what was deducted from the former was 
 added to the latter. The Schohast of Aristophanes'" distinctly 
 asserts that the thalamitae received lower wages, because they 
 had the shortest oars, and consequently the lightest labour : the 
 thranitee on the other hand from having the largest oars had 
 the greatest fatigue, and for this reason in the Sicihan expedi- 
 
 P. 119 A sqq. *" Lex. Scg. p. 298. ^^^ Acliarn. 1100'.
 
 CH. XXII.] 
 
 THE ARMY AND NAVY. 
 
 279 
 
 tion the trierarchs made them an additional allowance, together 
 with some other inferior persons in the vessel, probably the 
 steersman, the proreus, &c.; but that their regular pay was 
 higher we are neither told by Thucydides nor his interpreter^^^, 
 who have been adduced as authorities for the assertion. But 
 even if the pay was graduated according to rank, we could not 
 apportion the different rates for each description of seamen ; 
 especially as we are not able to ascertain with accuracy the 
 respective numbers of each class. It is indeed scarcely possible 
 even with the aid of conjecture to determine the proportion 
 which the sailors in a ship bore to the soldiers ; I will therefore 
 make some addition to what has been already observed on 
 this point with a view to render more intelligible our assump- 
 tion respecting the numbers of the crew of a trireme. 
 
 Triremes were of different kinds, either swift (ra^etat), or 
 military transports (o-rpaTtcwTiSe?, oTrXcTayayyol) : the latter 
 were completely filled with land forces, who, as they were put 
 on board solely for the purpose of being carried from one place 
 to another, were for this reason ineffective in battle, and there- 
 fore never called on to fight except on emergencies^^^; the 
 former kind however took on board no more than the full com- 
 plement of men {ifKrjpcofxa) which was necessary for working and 
 defending the ship. The troops on board the military trans- 
 ports in addition to the proper crews were, like all persons who 
 travelled by sea, called epibatee; 5100 men were transported in 
 40 such vessels, according to the account of Thucydides, making 
 altogether with their respective attendants more than 200 men 
 to a trireme; the Thebans sent 300 men to Pagasse in 2 tri- 
 remes^^% whose motion was consequently much retarded. The 
 hoplitse upon a few occasions transported themselves, per- 
 forming the labour of rowing with their own hands (avTepiraiY^K 
 The crews of the swift triremes however consisted of two 
 descriptions of men, of the soldiers or marines appointed to 
 
 ^«* vi. 31. 
 
 ^®5 Thucyd.i. 116, aiFords an instance 
 of this. 
 
 ^«« Thucyd. viii. 43 ; Xenoph. Hell. 
 
 V. 4, 56. There were 300 citizens who 
 were on board the triremes as epibatae 
 and no rowers. 
 
 ^"7 Thiic. iii. 18, cf. vi. Dl.
 
 280 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF [bK. II. 
 
 defend the vessels, who were also called epibatee ; and of the 
 sailors. These epibatse were entirely distinct from the land 
 soldiers, such as hoplitse, peltasts, and cavab-y'"' ; and belonged 
 to the vessel: but if it was an object to increase the usual 
 number, it was easy to give an additional quota of land soldiers, 
 as for instance the 30 to each trireme in Xerxes^ fleet. The 
 seamen, under whom I include the whole crew with the excep- 
 tion of the soldiers, are called sometimes servants (vTrrjpeTac), 
 sometimes sailors {vavTat): in a more limited sense however 
 the rowers {ipirai, KcoTTTjXdrac) are distinct from the servants 
 and sailors, and only comprise those who were employed at the 
 steerage, sails, cordage, pumps, &c. Finally, the rowers were 
 of three kinds, thranitse, zygit6e, and thalamitse. 
 
 If now the regular crew of the swift triremes amounted to 
 200 men, how was this number divided ? Meibomius reckons 
 180 rowers in three rows, so that there were 30 upon each bank, 
 on either side. This is a most singular hypothesis. For if 
 there were 180 rowers, there would only remain 20 for all the 
 rest of the crew, whereas the navigation of the ship alone would 
 have required this number, if we consider only the steersman, 
 the proreus, the celeustes, the trieraules, the nauphylax, the 
 toicharchs, the diopes, the eschareus, and the many others that 
 were unquestionably employed; and what room do we then 
 leave for the marines ? The supposition of Meibomius is 
 borrowed from the quinquireme, to which Polybius assigns 
 300 rowers, and 1 20 fighting men ; the former in five rows of 
 60 men, 30 on each side ; but his reason for crowding as many 
 rowers into the long side of the trireme, which he reckons at 
 105 feet, as into that of the quinquireme which measured 150 
 feet, is arbitrary. Not to go into farther details, the rowers 
 could not have amounted to more than 130 or 140 men, if we 
 leave a sufficient number for that part of the crew which 
 worked the ship, and for the epibatee. In the quinquireme the 
 rowers were to the marines in the ratio of 5 to 2 ; in a pente- 
 conter there were 30 men besides the 50 rowers"^ most of 
 whom were undoubtedly soldiers, as the number required for 
 
 Xenoph. Hell. i. 2, 4. i«9 Herod, vii. 184.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE ARMY AND NAVY. 281 
 
 the working of the vessel must in this case have been smaller ; 
 probably only about 10 men, so that the ratio of the rowers to 
 the fighters was again as 5 to 2. If therefore we reckon that 
 there were in a trireme 130 or 140 rowers, and 40 or 50 
 epibatee, in addition to 20 other seamen, the number of rowers 
 assumed is proportionally large. 
 
 I know only of two definite accounts of the number of the 
 epibatse which refer to particular occasions. Herodotus^"" tells 
 us that the Chians having revolted from Persia, and equipped a 
 hundred ships, distributed 40 opulent citizens as epibatee in 
 each trireme, which agrees perfectly with my computation. 
 Plutarch"' informs us that only 18 men fought upon deck on 
 board the Athenian triremes at the battle of Salamis; that of 
 these, 4 were bowmen and the others heavy-armed ; this esti- 
 mate is however singularly low. 
 
 With regard to the mode of fighting it may be observed, 
 that the rowers struck their opponents with oars, the epibatse 
 used arrows and darts at a distance, spears and swords in close 
 combat"". It must not however be supposed that the rowers 
 were so nearly defenceless. Isocrates"^ indeed in the passage 
 in which he complains that foreigners were then serving as 
 fighting men, and citizens as rowers, remarks, that in descents 
 upon the enemies' territory, the former fought as hoplitee, while 
 the latter landed with the cushions on which they sat; from 
 which it might be inferred that the rowers were unprovided with 
 any weapons of defence ; there can however be no doubt that 
 they were armed, only not in any regular manner, every one 
 providing for himself as he could, or as accident determined for 
 him, some as peltasts, bowmen, &c., that is, the thranitse and 
 zygitae"^, and probably the thalamitee also. They were there- 
 fore able to serve on land, which was necessarily the case with 
 the hopUtse who rowed themselves*'*. Since then the arming 
 of the rowers was irregular, some preparations were frequently 
 
 570 Herod, vi. 15. 
 
 571 Themist. 14. 
 
 '72 Compare for example Diod. xiii. 
 46. 
 
 '7<» 2vfxfiax. 16. 
 ^'* Thuc. iv. 3, 2. 
 
 7 5 See the passages referred to in 
 note 367.
 
 282 
 
 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 required in order to make them serviceable on land. Thus 
 Thrasyllus armed 5000 seamen belonging to his 50 triremes as 
 peltasts'''; and on an occasion mentioned by Thucydides'" the 
 sailors were obliged to be provided with shields before they 
 could serve upon land. This irregularity in the equipment of 
 the seamen is the less surprising, as we find that even the 
 hoplitse and the epibatee were not armed with perfect uni- 
 formity^ ; for, had this been the case, there would have been no 
 foundation for the story which Herodotus relates of an hoplite 
 in the battle of Plateese, who brought an anchor with him, in 
 order to fasten himself to the ground^^^; or an epibates, who 
 made use of a spear sickle [BopvBpeTravov) instead of a spear, as 
 Plato"^ mentions. 
 
 The land and sea forces generally received their pay and 
 provision at the same time ; if any portion of it remained in 
 arrear, it was commonly the pay; and the provision money, 
 as being necessary, was usually supplied first. In the expe- 
 dition of Timotheus against Corcyra, the mercenaries had 
 received three months^ provisions in advance, but no pay had 
 been supplied; so that there would have been considerable 
 danger of their going over to the enemy, if Timotheus had not 
 inspired them with confidence in his pecuniary resources by 
 making them a present of the provision money which they had 
 received in advance^^^ Demosthenes^^^ mentions another in- 
 stance, in which the trierarch had received the whole of the 
 provision money for his crew, though he obtained no more than 
 two months' pay for the whole time of his trierarchy. 
 
 Here too should be mentioned a suggestion of the same 
 statesman in the first Philippic, which however was never put 
 into execution. He proposed to maintain a standing army, in 
 order to carry on war against Macedon without intermission ; 
 10 ships and 2000 infantry, at an expense for each of 40 talents; 
 and 200 cavalry, at 12 talents a year: these sums however 
 were only to be given them as provision money ; he would not 
 allow any pay, but they were to have unlimited permission 
 
 57« Xenoph. lIcU. i. 2, 1, cf. i. 1, 24. 
 
 *'7 iv. 0. 
 
 *7" llurod. l\. 74. 
 
 ^79 Laches, p. 183 D. 
 
 ^»" Pseud-Aristot. (Ecou. ii. 23. 
 
 *«' C. Polycl. p. 1209, 12.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE ARMY AND NAVY. 283 
 
 to plunder. This proposal is worthy of remark, as having 
 no parallel in any Grecian author ; it is the outline of a plan 
 for embodying a military force to maintain itself at free 
 quarters, and at the same time to form a permanent standing 
 army; though its continuance was indeed limited to the dura- 
 tion of war. A standing army in time of peace would not only 
 have utterly ruined the finances, had it received pay, but, if it 
 had consisted of citizens, would have led to a military govern- 
 ment ; as the Thousand at Argos, who were required to devote 
 themselves exclusively to the exercise of arms, and received 
 pay for their services, took forcible possession of the supreme 
 power, and changed the democracy into an oligarchy^^^. The 
 Greeks were well aware that a standing army obtained a 
 greater degree of skill in the art of war ; but they were pre- 
 vented from introducing it by the nature of their constitutions : 
 for neither were they able to realize the ideal state of Plato, in 
 which the standing army, formed according to philosophical and 
 moral principles, is at the head of the government ; nor could 
 they return to the oriental form of castes, an institution of 
 universal adoption in remote antiquity, and under which Attica 
 had in early times had her military caste ; nor, lastly, could they 
 have endured the oppression of a military government. The 
 Romans were of the same opinion : even after their government 
 had declined into a barbarous military despotism, it was never- 
 theless considered indecorous that an armed force should reside 
 in the capital, for the purpose, as it were, of overawing the 
 people ; and in order to preserve the decorum to which they 
 owed the continuance of all ancient forms, and even of the 
 senate itself, the imperial guards at Rome were compelled to 
 wear the civil toga, and their helmets and shields were kept in 
 the armoury^°^ 
 
 With regard to the scheme of Demosthenes mentioned 
 above, it seems strange, according to our notions, that the 
 soldiers were to have first received money merely for provision, 
 and to have had no pay whatever ; as it appears more natural to 
 
 ^^'■^ Diod. xii. 75, 80; Time. v. 81 ; Puusaa. ii. 20 ; Aristot. Polit. v. 4. 
 '^-' See Lipsius ad Tacit. Hist. i. oC.
 
 284 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF [bK. II. 
 
 have given them pay, and have suppUed provisions by means of 
 requisition and quartering: but the former method was too 
 tedious and difficult in an enemy's country, if it was to be 
 exacted regularly; and the latter was very rarely practised in the 
 Greek states. In the first place, it was unnecessary, war being 
 generally carried on in the favourable time of year, and the life 
 of a camp in so mild a climate was healthy and pleasant ; in the 
 second place, it was inadmissible upon military in a foreign, and 
 on political principles in a friendly, country. The ancients, on 
 account of the freedom of their governments, would not, any 
 more than England, have submitted to an institution from 
 which every sort of oppression and injustice is inseparable, and 
 which endangers the very existence of liberty; considering too 
 the greater dissoluteness of their morals (particularly with 
 regard to the intercourse of the sexes and their proneness to 
 unnatural vices), the susceptibility of their passions, the want of 
 discipline in the armies, and the great claims and pretensions of 
 the soldiers, the necessary consequences of such an institution 
 would have been murders, insurrections, and revolutions. In 
 the case of friendly states it was first necessary to ask whether 
 an army in march or a naval force could be received into the 
 city alone, and even this was frequently denied : if permission 
 was granted, everything was paid for on the spot. When 
 Athens sent an army to the assistance of the Thebans, they 
 received it in so friendly a manner, that the hoplitee and cavalry 
 being encamped without the city, the Thebans admitted them into 
 their houses : but in how marked a manner does Demosthenes 
 boast that no disturbance ensued, " The three most splendid 
 encomia of your virtues,^' he says' ^% " the Thebans showed on 
 that day to all the Greeks; the first of your courage, the second 
 of your justice, the third of your moderation: for by giving 
 into your power what with them and all people is guarded with 
 the greatest sanctity, their wives and children, they showed that 
 they had a firm assurance of your continence : and in that they 
 judged rightly, for after the army had entered the city, no 
 inhabitant made any complaint against you, no, not even an 
 
 ^"* Tro Corona, j). 2'J'J, extr.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE ARMY AND NAVY. 285 
 
 unjust one/' The Persians however managed their army in a 
 different manner : in their expedition to Greece they encamped 
 indeed in the open fields, but were supported by the inhabitants : 
 the reception and maintenance of Xerxes' army cost the 
 Thasians alone, for their towns situated upon the main-land, 
 400 talents, which were paid out of the public money, so that 
 individuals did not directly bear the burden; and the Abderite 
 said with justice that the whole state would have been destroyed 
 if Xerxes had breakfasted as well as dined there^^\ Datames 
 the Persian provisioned his troops in the same manner in a 
 foreign country^^\ The Romans oppressed the provinces most 
 grievously with their armies, especially for winter quarters ; the 
 praetors, when bought off by one city, were not ashamed to 
 burden another : these bribes were called the Vectigal Presto- 
 rium, whence in subsequent times the Epidemeticum arose^". 
 
 Whether the allowance for provision was given out in 
 money or in kind, it was the imperative duty of the generals to 
 attend to the provisioning of the troops, especially for voyages, 
 when food could not be purchased day by day. It usually hap- 
 pened that a large market established itself in any place where 
 the armies either remained for a time, or were expected. Here 
 the soldiers supplied their wants, and upon a march their 
 servants and beasts of burden carried provisions in the rear ; 
 suttlers and handicraftsmen followed for the sake of their own 
 gain : Datames the Persian even supported a number of these 
 traffickers, in order to have a share in their profits, and pro- 
 hibited all others from entering into competition with them^^^. 
 With great armies the supply of provisions was necessarily on 
 a large scale : the Grecian army at Plataese was followed by 
 large stores from the Peloponnese, the care of which belonged 
 to the attendants"^; in like manner the Persian army was 
 followed by whole fleets of store-ships. The provident Nicias 
 stated it as an indispensable requisite to the undertaking of the 
 Sicilian expedition, that wheat and roasted barley should be 
 
 ^^^ Herod, vii. 118 sqq. ; tioned by Tacitus, Hist. i. 66". 
 
 =^^ Pseud- Aristot. CEcon. ii. 24. | ^^^ Pseud- Aristot. ut sup. 
 
 5^7 Burmann de Yect. Pop. Rom.xii. \ ^^^ Herod, ix. 39, cf. 50. 
 An action of similar oppression is men-
 
 286 
 
 PAY AND PROVISIONING OF 
 
 [bk. II, 
 
 sent from Attica to Sicily, and that they should take with them 
 hired bakers, who were procured from the mills by a compul- 
 sory levy'''; the provision fleet collected at Corcyra, consisting 
 of 30 corn vessels, with the bakers and other handicraftsmen, 
 such as stone-masons and carpenters, and the implements 
 required for a siege; also 100 smaller vessels were constrained 
 to attend the store ships, and many others, both smaller and 
 larger, followed the army for the sake of traffic^^'. When such 
 was the case, however, the soldiers doubtless purchased their 
 provision either from individuals or from the state, which had 
 only the care of procuring supphes, without anything being 
 given freely to the soldiers, unless perchance no provision 
 money had been paid them. When Timotheus besieged Samos, 
 a scarcity of provisions was produced by the concourse of so 
 many strangers; he therefore prohibited the selling of ground 
 corn, and did not allow it to be sold plain in less quantities than 
 a medimnus, or any liquids in less quantities than a metretes; 
 by these means the strangers were obliged to bring their provi- 
 sions with them, and they sold whatever remained unconsumed; 
 while the taxiarchs and lochagi bought food by wholesale, and 
 retailed it among the soldiers^'^ The same must be con- 
 sidered to have been the case in the Sicilian expedition, and 
 other similar occasions. If the provision was supplied in kind, 
 which was necessarily more general with the sea than with the 
 land service, the commanders received the siteresion, and with 
 that money they purchased a store of provisions. The trierarchs 
 supplied their inferiors with barley-meal (aX(j>tTa), cheese, and 
 onions^^% or garlic, which were carried in nets"*^*; the maza was 
 baked from the barley-meaP®% with water and oiP'^; and if it 
 
 **' Thuc. vi. 22, -where the bakers 
 are called T]vayKa(Tix€voL cfifxiadoi, as, 
 although they received pay, they had 
 been pressed into this expedition. 
 npos fiepos Duker rightly interprets 
 pro rata portione : it is not however in 
 reference to the corn, but means that 
 a proportional number should be taken 
 from each mill, eV tcov fivXavav rrpos 
 fjifpos, for example, two out of each. 
 
 23 ; Polyjen. 
 
 591 Time. vi. 30,44. 
 
 ^^^ Pseud-Aristot. ii. 
 iii. 10, 10. 
 
 593 Plutarch, de Glor. Ath. fi. 
 
 59^ Thence the saying, (XKopohov eV 
 bLKTvois, see Suidas in v. crKopodiois. 
 
 •95 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 1105. 
 
 59« Hesychius and Zonaras in v.
 
 CH. XXII.] 
 
 THE ARMY AND NAVY. 
 
 287 
 
 was wished particularly to stimulate the rowers^ wine also was 
 added^^^ Probably each man received a choenix of barley-meal 
 a day : a comic poet indeed says of a man, who boasted of 
 eating 2i medimni in a day, that he would consume the pro- 
 visions of a long trireme^®% although what he ate was in fact 
 only 120 choenices; but who will require of a jester accuracy 
 on such a subject as this ? Ptolemy gave the Rhodians, for 
 the provision of 10 triremes, 20,000 artabse of corn'^% probably 
 of wheat, making 10 artabse a year for each man, if we reckon 
 200 to a trireme; which amounts to almost 1^ choenix a day, 
 if large artabee are meant, and if small, only three-quarters of a 
 chcenix. 
 
 To estimate the amount of the pay and provision money 
 required for a war, another datum is necessary besides the 
 numerical force of the army and the rate of the pay, viz., the 
 length of the campaign. As soon as the campaign was over, 
 the payment of the troops ceased ; even mercenaries did not 
 constantly receive wages, but were paid for a portion only of 
 the time®°^ In early times war was carried on with the Lace- 
 daemonians for four or five months ; but Philip made no differ- 
 ence between summer and winter^"'. Yet as early as in the 
 Peloponnesian war, armies were paid in winter, as in Sicily 
 and elsewhere ; and Pericles used regularly to keep 60 ships 
 eight months at sea, and to pay them for the whole time*"*: 
 these alone must have cost 480 talents a year, if each man 
 received a drachma a day. But how could Athens have raised 
 pay and provision money for more than 60,000 men in the 
 Sicilian expedition, the cost being 3600 talents in a year ? We 
 must not therefore wonder that, notwithstanding the high 
 tributes and the oppression of the allies (though the indepen- 
 dent confederate states in great measure paid their own troops), 
 a scarcity of supplies quickly arose; nor need we be surprised 
 
 ^^7 Thuc. iii. 49 ; comp. ScheflFer 
 Mil. Nav. iv. 1. This [xd^a is the 
 olvovTTa, Athen. iii. p. 114 F. 
 
 59« Athen. x. p. 415 C. 
 
 f,93 Polvb. V. 80. 
 
 ^'•^ For an instance of this see Thu- 
 cyd. viii. 45. 
 
 «'*i Demosth. Philipp. iii. p. 123. 
 ^''■^ Plutarch. Pericl. 11.
 
 288 EQUIPMENT OF THE FLEET. [bK. II. 
 
 that Pericles, who, in the beginning of the war, kept an equally 
 large force on foot, although not throughout the whole year, 
 was compelled to have recourse to the public treasure. 
 
 Chapter XXIII. 
 
 Equipment of the Fleet. Implements for Sieges. 
 
 The expenses of war were also considerably increased by the 
 equipment of fleets, and the preparation of machines used in 
 war, and of instruments for sieges. 
 
 Besides the ships which were built in time of peace, they 
 were accustomed, as soon as any severe struggle was apprehended, 
 to apply themselves with extraordinary zeal to the construction 
 of vessels ; yet, before the ships could be ready to sail, there re- 
 mained always much to be done in order to complete their equip- 
 ment ; part of which was furnished by the state, and part by the 
 trierarch at his own cost. Besides the swift triremes, it was also 
 necessary to provide many transports (oX/taSe?), auxiliary vessels 
 {vTTTjpeTt/ca TrXota), and cavalry transports {iTrirayeoya irXoia); 
 which latter, although the Greeks had taken horses with them to 
 the siege of Troy, and the Persians had employed many ships of 
 this description in the war against Greece, were yet for the first 
 time regularly introduced at Athens in the second year of the 
 Peloponnesian war, and were afterwards frequently used^°\ On 
 rare occasions only it happened that the Athenians had a fleet 
 equipped and ready for battle, such as that appointed in Olymp. 
 87, 2 (B.C. 431), when it was decreed that every year the 100 
 best triremes should be selected, to which trierarchs were imme- 
 diately assigned, in order that Attica might be defended in the 
 event of an attack from the sea; and at the same time 1000 
 talents were ordered to be laid by for the same object'"*. 
 
 Thuc. ii, 56, iv. 42, vi. 43, and Fals. Leg. p. 336 ; Andoc. de Pace, p. 
 
 elsewhere; Demostli. Philipp. i. p 
 46, 5 ; Plutarch. Pericl. 35. Concerning 
 the Persians see Diod. xi. 3 ; Herod, 
 vii. 97. 
 
 •^^^ Thuc. ii. 24, viii. 15 ; ^sch. de 
 
 92 ; Suid. in v. a^vaaos. The money 
 was laid by only once, and not annu- 
 ally, as some writers have erroneously 
 supposed.
 
 CH. XXIII.] IMPLEMENTS FOR SIEGES. 2S9 
 
 The preparations for sieges were particularly expensive, 
 since much carpenters' work and masonry, and many handi- 
 craftsmen, were required for these purposes: machines for 
 attack and defence were used in early times, not only in the 
 Peloponnesian war, but even at an earlier period, as, for ex- 
 ample, by Miltiades at Paros, and by Pericles at the siege of 
 Samos; although the art of besieging did not attain its greatest 
 perfection among the Greeks until the time of Demetrius 
 Poliorcetes. That considerable outlays were made for missile 
 weapons is evident from several passages in ancient writers. 
 With regard to Athens, it will be sufficient to mention the two 
 decrees®"^ by which honours were conferred on Demochares and 
 Lycurgus; the former, for having procured arms, darts, and 
 machines; the latter, for having brought arms and 50,000 darts 
 into the Acropolis. 
 
 Chapter XXIV. 
 
 Estimate of the War Expenditure of Athens. 
 
 If these several heads are added together, it will be at once 
 evident how vast must have been the whole expenses of 
 a war after the time that Pericles had introduced the pay of the 
 forces; whereas in earlier times the building and equipment of 
 the fleets alone caused any expense to the state. The fine of 
 50 talents, to which Miltiades was condemned on account of 
 the failure of his expedition with 70 ships against Paros, might 
 therefore have been taken as equivalent to the whole expense, 
 as Nepos''' thinks it was, did we not know that this sum was a 
 common fine, without any regard to a particular compensation. 
 The siege of Samos in Olymp. 84, 4 (b. c. 441), appears, 
 according to Diodorus, to have cost 200 talents; for Pericles 
 required a contribution to this amount, as an indemnification 
 for the expenses which had been incurred^". Pericles must 
 however have reckoned very leniently in this case; for a nine 
 
 ««5 At the end of the Lives of the 1 ^"^ Miltiad. 7. 
 Ten Oratore, ii. iii. 1 ''' Diod. xii. 28 ; cf. Thuc. i. 1 17- 
 
 U
 
 290 
 
 ESTIMATE OF THE 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 months' siege by land and sea, in which, according to the 
 account of Thucydides, not less than 199 triremes were em- 
 ployed, or at any rate a large part of this number for a consi- 
 derable time, must evidently have caused a greater expense; 
 and the statement therefore of Isocrates and Nepos'*^^ that 
 1200 talents were expended upon it, 'appears to be by no 
 means exaggerated. 
 
 But the expenses of the Peloponnesian war are the most 
 extraordinary in the financial history of Athens. If we assume 
 that the ships employed at the beginning of the war received 
 only six months' pay, they must have cost 1500 talents; and in 
 this number the forces employed at the siege of Potidaea are not 
 included. This siege was extremely expensive, having been 
 continued uninterruptedly during both summer and winter for 
 two years; Thucydides reckons the expense at 2000^°^, Iso- 
 crates at 2400 talents, a part of which Pericles took from the 
 public treasure*'^^ A separate war tax of 200 talents was levied 
 for the siege of Mytilene, and 12 ships were dispatched for the 
 purpose of collecting money from the allies^''. No enterprise 
 went so far beyond the resources of the Athenian state as the 
 Sicilian expedition. The annual pay alone amounted, as we 
 have already seen, to 3600 talents, nearly the double of the 
 whole annual revenue of Athens, if we take it at the highest 
 estimate; and at how great an amount must we reckon the 
 other expenses of this war ? By these means both money and 
 provisions soon almost wholly failed; nor were the subsidies 
 furnished by the Egestseans at all considerable, viz. 60 talents 
 
 ^''^ Thiic. i. IIG, 117; Isocrat. de 
 Antidosi, p. C9; Nepos Timoth. 1. 
 
 ^°^ Thuc. ii. 70, where the reading 
 XiXta is undoubtedly false, Isocrat. de 
 Antid. p. 70. Diodorus (xii. 46) 
 reckons the expenses some months 
 before the surrender at more than 
 1000 talents. 
 
 «•<» Thuc. iii. 17, ii. 13. According 
 to the latter passage 3700 talents were 
 taken out of the troa-sury, wliicli Dio- 
 dorus (xii. 40) less accurately calls 
 
 4000. Barthelemy reckons 3000 for 
 the public works of Pericles, and 700 
 for the first part of the siege (Anach. 
 torn. i. note 8), This assumption is 
 however quite arbitrary ; Potidaea and 
 the works of building and art might 
 have cost more than 5000 talents, and 
 those 3700 have been only an advance 
 from the public treasure, in addition 
 to what was paid for out of the current 
 revenues. 
 
 "" Thuc. iii. 10.
 
 CH. XXIV.] WAR EXPENDITURE OF ATHENS. 
 
 291 
 
 given at the very commencement, as monthly pay for 60 ships, 
 and 30 talents sent at a subsequent period^ '^ There was little 
 plunder taken, although 100 talents were once obtained from 
 that source® ^^: the remittances from Athens were by no means 
 large, 20, 120, or 300 talents, and these, as it appears, eveii 
 came, in part at least, from the public treasure^ ^*, to which, both 
 then and afterwards, they were compelled to have recourse, in 
 order to support the expenses of the war, for which purpose 
 indeed it had been originally collected. Nothing but a fortu- 
 nate issue could have put Athens in a condition to defray the 
 immense sums required for pay; without which however it 
 would have been impossible to adopt so vast a plan. If Pericles 
 had not introduced the pay of the soldiers, Athens could not 
 have carried on the Peloponnesian war for so long a time; nor 
 again, could the youthful imagination of Alcibiades have con- 
 ceived the lofty notion of obtaining a footing in Sicily, as a new 
 centre from which they might subdue Carthage and Libya, 
 Italy, and, finally, the Peloponnese®^'; the people and the 
 soldiers were moreover favourably inclined to this expedition, 
 because they hoped to receive money immediately, and to make 
 conquests, by which they would be enabled to receive their pay 
 without intermission^ ^^. 
 
 In the age of Demosthenes, also, much treasure, levied 
 chiefly by property taxes, was applied to the uses of war; but 
 with a large expenditure little was eflfected. A fruitless expe- 
 dition to Pylse cost, together with the expenses incurred by 
 private individuals, above 200 talents*''; Isocrates complains 
 of the loss of more than 1000 talents, which had been given to 
 foreigners*'®; Demosthenes of the squandering of more than 
 
 «'2 Diod. xiii. 6. 
 
 «'3 Diod. ibid. 
 
 ^^* See Corp. Inscript. No. 144, with 
 the remarks, p. 208. 
 
 ^^^ Thuc. vi. 15, 90; Isocrat. 2u/i- 
 /xax- 29; Plutarch. Alcib, 17- The 
 idea was new; for althoiigh in the 
 Knights of Aristophanes (vs. 174, 1300) 
 a plan is '^hinted at for attacking Car- 
 
 thage, it only owes its existence to a 
 false reading. In both places KaX^j;- 
 Scop should evidently be read for Ko/j- 
 XV^^^f as the Scholiast at vs. 1300 
 writes, and as the sense requires in vs. 
 174. 
 
 «io Thuc. vi. 24. 
 
 «i7 Demosth. de Fals. Leg.p.367,21, 
 
 ^''^ Isocrat. Areopag. 4. 
 U 2
 
 292 
 
 ESTIMATE OF THE 
 
 [bk. II. 
 
 1500, which, as iEschines remarks, were expended not upon 
 the soldiers, but upon the ostentatious splendour of the gene- 
 rals'", at the very time they lost the allied cities and their ships. 
 The state had been impoverished by the theorica, while indivi- 
 duals had enriched themselves; there was not in the miUtary 
 chest money enough for a single day's march"'"; and if any 
 funds were collected for war, the mismanagement and maladmi- 
 nistration would surpass all belief, did we not know that the 
 same mischief has recurred in all times. Commanders or 
 demagogues, who received pay for the troops, drew it for 
 empty j)^aces^^\ as was the expression; in the same manner that 
 in modern times generals have received pay for what were termed 
 men of straw, or soldiers that existed only on the roll. To 
 ascertain the extent of these practices, commissioners were sent 
 out to discover whether there were as many mercenaries as the 
 generals reported; these inquirers, however, frequently allowed 
 themselves to be bribed'". The trierarchs, as early even as in 
 the time of the poet Aristophanes, were accused of embezzling 
 the pay of part of the crew, and stopping the unoccupied aper- 
 tures for the oars in their ships, in order that it might not be seen 
 that there was a deficiency of rowers'^^ 
 
 In the mean time the public money was squandered away 
 by generals such as Chares and many resembling him, who 
 were distinguished by every kind of profligacy. If in an age of 
 simplicity and decorum, Themistocles was not ashamed to drive 
 through the Ceramicus in the morning with a carriage full of 
 courtesans'*^, it is easy to understand how Alcibiades, who, 
 
 '^3 Demosth. Olynth. iii. p. 36, 8, 
 (and thence nepX a-vvrd^. p. 174, 11,) 
 jEsch. de Fals. Leg. p. 249. 
 
 '^^'^ Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 690. 
 
 ^■^' This is the meaning of fiio-Oo- 
 <j>op€7v iv TO) ^fviKa Kevais x^^pats"? 
 TEschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 536. Others 
 cheated the soldiers, as e. g. Memnon 
 of Rhodes and Cleomenes. See Aris- 
 tot. CEcon. ii. 29, 39. 
 
 °'^^ These are the e^eraaTolj ^Esch. 
 c. Timarch. p. 131, nepl napanpecr^i. p. 
 
 339, Lex. Seg. p. 252. The passage 
 in the oration Trepl (rvvrd^eas p. 167, 
 17, seems also to refer to the exetastae ; 
 those, however, mentioned in the de- 
 cree published by Chishull Ant. As. p. 
 164, from Ains worth, which probably 
 belongs to Athens, are of a different 
 description. 
 
 ^"^ Schol. Aristoph. Pac. 1233. 
 
 '" Heraclides ap. Athen. xii. p. 533 
 D.
 
 CH. XXIV.] WAR EXPENDITURE OF ATHENS. 293 
 
 notwithstanding his extraordinary talents, was a man of the 
 most immoral and irrehgious character, did not scruple (as at 
 least his enemies said of him**^) to carry women about with him 
 in his campaigns, and to embezzle 200 talents; how Chabrias, 
 according to Theopompus, was not able to remain in Athens on 
 account of his debauched habits; and how, according to the 
 same authority, Chares had with him in the field women even 
 of the lowest description, and applied the public money to uses 
 wholly at variance with its proper destination. But the Athe- 
 nians could not censure such a course of habits, for they them- 
 selves lived in an equally depraved manner, the young men 
 with female flute-players and courtesans, the old in gambling; 
 while they consumed more money in public banquetings and 
 distributions of food than for the real service of the state, and 
 allowed themselves to be entertained in the market place at 
 a triumphal festival for a battle won over the mercenaries 
 of Philip with an expense of 60 talents, which Chares had 
 received from Delphi^^^ Theopompus is described as censori- 
 ous for having painted from nature the dissolute manners of a 
 corrupt age : for most people are inclined to look at everything 
 on its fairest side, especially if they view it from a distance, 
 when all the passions are silent, and the benevolent feeling 
 which is implanted in the heart of man is not contradicted by 
 immediate and personal experience; but honour is due to the 
 historian who knows how to distinguish the covering from the 
 substance, and, like the judge of the infernal regions, drags the 
 souls before his judgment seat, naked and stripped of all pomp 
 and pageantry. 
 
 Timotheus, the son of Conon, deserves to be honourably 
 mentioned as a warrior equal to his father, and among all the 
 Athenian generals of being that one who knew how^ to carry 
 his enterprises into execution with the least outlay of money, 
 and therefore without burdening the allies, and making himself 
 and his country odious through extortion. I pass over his 
 
 625 
 
 Lysias c. Alcib. XetTTOTo^. i. p. I ^'^^ Theopompus ap. Atlieu. xii. p. 
 548. I 532 B, sqq.
 
 294 
 
 ESTIMATE OF THE 
 
 [bK. II. 
 
 other merits, which will be mentioned hereafter; but his skill 
 in maintaining his soldiers ought not to be left unnoticed. 
 Timotheus generally received little or nothing in the beginning 
 of the campaign; though there arose the greatest scarcity in the 
 army, he was still successful in the war, and paid his soldiers to 
 the last obolus*^^ He subdued four and twenty states with less 
 expense than the siege of Melos had occasioned in the Pelopon- 
 nesian war^"; the siege of Potidsea, which had cost such vast 
 sums in the time of Pericles, he carried on with money which 
 he had raised himself, together with the contributions of the 
 Thracian cities"*; according to Nepos he gained in the war 
 against Cotys 1200 talents of prize-money®'". In the expedi- 
 tion against Olynthus, having no silver money, he issued a 
 coinage of copper tokens, which he induced the merchants to 
 take by promising them that they might use it in paying for 
 whatever property either in land or plunder they might pur- 
 chase, and he pledged himself to redeem whatever should 
 remain over^^'. In the expedition round the Peloponnese to 
 Corcyra, there was likewise great scarcity; for Timotheus had 
 received only 13 talents®'^ He accordingly compelled each of 
 the trierarchs to give pay to the sailors to the amount of 7 
 minas, for which he pledged his own property®*'; afterwards 
 being unable to furnish any more pay to the troops, he gave them 
 provision-money for three months in advance, in order that 
 they might believe he was in the expectation of large sums 
 which were only detained by the unfavourable state of the 
 weather®'*; and in the mean time he sent for a fresh supply of 
 money from Athens for his numerous fleet®". But he and 
 Iphicrates also paid away some of the prize-money on this 
 occasion®'®. Lastly, Timotheus kept 30 triremes and 8000 pel- 
 
 **' Isocrat. de Antidosi, p. 72, ed. 
 Orell. 
 
 "'^^ Ibid. p. 70. 
 
 «='» Ibid. p. 70. 
 
 "^o Nepos Timoth. i. 
 
 "^ Pseud-Aiistot. CEcon. ii. 2,23; 
 Polyjen. iii. 10, 1 . 
 
 ^^* Isocrat. ut sup. p. 68. 
 
 "^^ Orat. c.Timoth. (in Demosthenes) 
 p. 1187, 1188. 
 
 ^^* Pseud -Aristot. (Econ. ut sup. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. Hell. v. 4, 66, 
 
 ^^ Diod.xv. 47,cf.xvi.57. Xenophon 
 indeed (Hell. vi. 2, 23) relates the ac- 
 counts, which Diodorus ascribes to 
 both, of Iphicrates alone, and uudoubt-
 
 CH. XXIV.] WAR EXPENDITURE OF ATHENS. 
 
 295 
 
 tasts in pay (with which he besieged Samos for eleven months), 
 sustaining them wholly from the enemy's country, whereas 
 Pericles had not been able to take the same island without 
 incurring a vast expense^". 
 
 edly with more con-ectness ; but it can 
 be safely asserted of Timotheus that 
 he assisted himself at that time with 
 
 plunder. 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. ut sup. p. 69; Aristot. 
 (Ecou. ut sup. Polyajn. L 10, 5, 9.
 
 20(1 
 
 BOOK III. 
 
 ON THE ORDINARY REVENUES OF THE ATHENIAN STATE. 
 
 Chapter I. 
 
 The different branches of the Public Revenue in Athens and other 
 Greek Republics, 
 
 The revenues of the Athenian state may, in like manner with 
 its expenditure, be classed under two divisions; the one com- 
 prising the ordinary income, from which were defrayed the cur- 
 rent expenses in time of peace; the other including all extra- 
 ordinary resources for mihtary preparations and the carrying 
 on of war. 
 
 The present being the first attempt which has been made to 
 investigate this subject^, it will be necessary at the outset to 
 ascertain what species of revenues were thought by the Greeks 
 
 ^ In the following inquiries I have 
 been nearly unassisted by the labours 
 of any predecessor, with the exception 
 of what had been written on the sub- 
 ject of the liturgies, and what Manso 
 (Sparta, vol. ii. p. 493—505), had ad- 
 duced in reference to the period of 
 the Peloponnesian war. The errors 
 of this last dissertation I have some- 
 times mentioned, and others I have 
 passed over in silence, as they are not 
 of great importance in a Avriter who is 
 treating of a totally different subject. 
 After the comi)letion of my labours, 
 the second volume of Becker's " De- 
 mosthenes as Siatosman and Orator" 
 appeared, which contains something on 
 the subject of finance, as well as on 
 tlie judicial and military systems: 
 without annoying the intelligent and 
 imassumiiig author wiili uusca-sonable 
 
 censure, or wishing to raise myself 
 unjustly above others, I may assert 
 with truth, that I derived no informa- 
 tion from it, nor did I feel myself in- 
 clined to refute any of his statements, 
 as I am convinced that the author will 
 himself perceive the incompleteness 
 of his investigations. The following 
 singular production may also be men- 
 tioned : " De I'economie des anciens 
 gouvememens comparee a celle des 
 gouvernemens modemes, par Mr. Pre- 
 vost, ]SIemoire lu dans I'assemblee 
 publique de I'acade'mie royale des sci- 
 ences et belles-lettres de Prusse, du 5 
 Juin, 1783. Berlin, 17o3, 8vo." The 
 autlior of this Memoir, wlio has distin- 
 guished himself in other departments 
 of literature, here, from want of know- 
 ledge, wanders into vague generalities, 
 and loses himself in idle dibquisitioua
 
 CII. I.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 297 
 
 to be the best^ and what taxes to be most easily borne by the 
 people. 
 
 Of all taxes, none are more repugnant to notions of liberty 
 (not in a general sense only, but also according to the princi- 
 ples entertained by the ancients), than taxes upon persons. 
 At Athens it was a recognised principle, that taxes were to be 
 imposed upon property, and not upon persons^; and even the 
 property of the citizens was only taxed on occasions of emer- 
 gency, or under an honourable form. In the state of Athens, 
 and doubtless in all the other Grecian republics, no direct tax 
 was laid upon property, except perhaps a duty on slaves, and 
 the extraordinary w^ar taxes, together wdth the liturgies, which 
 latter were considered a mark of distinction. In republics 
 there was no regular land tax or tithe {BeKdrrj), and, with the 
 exception of the sacred and national property, no land in Attica 
 was, after the early times of this state, ever subject to a ground 
 rent; and even at that remote period, this tax was not paid 
 into the public treasury, but to the nobles, in their right of 
 proprietors of the soil. The Greeks, moreover, were equally 
 unacquainted with a house tax, of which the existence has been 
 supposed from the misconception of a passage in an ancient 
 author"*. The best and most popular revenues were necessarily 
 
 without value or foundation. In this 
 Memoir, publicly read before an aca- 
 demy of sciences, I do not remember 
 to have met with anything of import- 
 ance, but the truly anti-Xenophontean 
 and philanthropic proposal, to change 
 a number of Sundays into working 
 days, in order to promote the prosperity 
 of the people ! 
 
 ^ Demosth. c. Androt. p. 609, 23. 
 
 3 See below, chap. 3. A single pas- 
 sage, from which it might be supposed 
 that there existed a land tax, I will 
 examine in this note. In an inscrip- 
 tion in Coi-p. Inscript. No. 101, ac- 
 cording to which, by a decree of the 
 demus Piraeus, certain honours and 
 privileges are granted to Callida- 
 mas of CholUdae, an Athenian, the 
 following words occur : TeXeli/ 6c avrov 
 
 TO. axiTCL riKr} iv ra Sjy/xo), anep av koI 
 nftpateiy, Kai. fj-rj cKXeyeiv Trap avTov 
 Tov bT]fxapxov TO iyKrqTiKov. From this 
 it is evident, that whoever possessed 
 landed property in a demus to which 
 he did not belong, paid something for 
 the eyKTT](Tis or cyKrqpa: this, how- 
 ever, was a tax paid to the demus, and 
 not to the state ; and the reason of its 
 being paid was, that the proprietor 
 was not a member of the particular 
 demus. "With regard to the reX?;, they 
 refer undoubtedly to the liturgies and 
 the extraordinary taxes, together with 
 certain duties raised by the corpora- 
 tions. Taxes on houses and land only 
 existed in states under the govern- 
 ment of a tjTant. Of the word Tikos 
 more is said in book iv. cli. 5.
 
 298 
 
 THE DIFFERENT BRANCHES OF 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 those which arose from the pubHc lands or domains: in addition 
 to these rents there were indirect taxes which fell upon. all the 
 inhabitants, and direct taxes which fell upon the aliens; there 
 were also the justice fees and fines. But over and above these 
 domestic imposts, Athens contrived in the tributes of the con- 
 federates a peculiar source of regular revenue, which at its first 
 establishment was the chief means of her power, though after- 
 wards it became an accessory cause of her destruction. 
 
 All the ordinary revenues of Athens may thus be brought 
 into the following four classes: duties (reX??), arising partly 
 from public domains, including the mines, partly from customs 
 and excise, and some taxes upon industry and persons, which 
 only extended to the aliens and slaves: fines {TLfjb7]fiaTa), toge- 
 ther with justice fees and the proceeds of confiscated property 
 (BTj/jLLOTrpara): tributes of the allied or subject states {cf>6poL): 
 and ordinary liturgies (Xecrovpylat iyKVKXtoi). These comj^re- 
 hend nearly all the diff'erent kinds of revenues which Aristopha- 
 nes* ascribes to the state of Athens, when he mentions duties 
 (reXi]), the other hundredths {Ta9 dWas eKaroaTds), tributes, 
 prytaneia (in which, with the inaccuracy of a poet, he includes 
 the fines), markets, harbours, and confiscations: besides these 
 he specifies one other head of revenue, respecting which no 
 certain information can be given. 
 
 With the single exception of the tributes, this enumeration 
 would apply with equal truth to the other states of Greece. 
 Even the liturgies, which for a time were considered as an 
 institution peculiar to the Athenians, and the extraordinary 
 property taxes, were common at least to all democracies, and 
 were even established in certain aristocracies or oligarchies. 
 Aristotle' states in general terms, that under a democracy the 
 
 * Vesp. 657j sqq., where fiiadovs 
 creates a difficulty. Perhaps it might 
 mean pay for the soldiers, -which Athens 
 received from foreign nations in addi 
 tion to the tributes, as e. g. in the 
 Sicilian war from the Egestaeans: it 
 might, however, signify the rents of 
 lands, as /iirr^oifor fiLaOaxras is correct 
 Greek. The jjlictOoI Tpirjpaij^ias (Xe- 
 
 noph. (Ecou. 2, 6), cannot be meant, 
 since it would not have suited the 
 pmposo of Aristoplianes to mention 
 these any more than the elcrf^opd. 
 [Compare the author's dissertation on 
 the silver mines of Laurion, note 114. 
 Transl.] 
 •• Polit. V. 5.
 
 CH. I.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 299 
 
 chief persons will be oppressed either by dividing their property, 
 or consuming their incomes by liturgies. That the Athenian 
 colonies, as Potideea for example, collected property taxes*b; 
 that we meet with liturgies at Byzantium, the population of 
 which was in part Athenian" ; with property taxes, choregia, 
 and other liturgies, in Siphnos^; is nothing more than might 
 naturally have been expected ; but at -^gina the choregia was in 
 existence even before the Persian war'; at Mytilene during the 
 Peloponnesian war®; at Thebes in the time of Pelopidas and 
 Epaminondas^"; and at Orchomenus at a very early period*'. 
 At Rhodes the wealthy citizens performed the trierarchy in the 
 same manner as at Athens, their expenses being partly compen- 
 sated by those who were less rich than themselves, by which 
 means the latter became their debtors, as at Athens in the case 
 of the advance of the property tax {'Trpoet,cr(f>opdy'^', and, lastly, 
 we find the institution of liturgies widely extended through the 
 Greek cities of Asia Minor. 
 
 What I have here said upon the different sorts of revenues 
 in the Grecian republics, is confirmed by the introduction to 
 the Treatise on Political Economy attributed to Aristotle. The 
 author distinguishes economy into four kinds; the royal eco- 
 nomy, the economy of satraps, the political, and the private. 
 The first of these he calls the greatest and most simple; the 
 third the most various and easy; and the last the most various 
 and least considerable. To the royal he assigns four depart- 
 ments, coinage, exportation, importation, and expenditure. With 
 regard to money, he tells us, the king must consider what 
 description of coin is to be issued, and when it is to be made 
 current at a higher or lower rate. With regard to exports and 
 imports, what quantity it is profitable to take from the satraps 
 as a tax in kind'% and at what time, and how the goods so 
 
 *b See book iv.,note 220. 
 ^ Decree of the Byzantines in De- 
 mosth. de Corona, p. 265, 10. 
 
 7 Isocrat. ^ginet. 17. 
 
 8 Herod, v. 83. 
 
 ® Antiphon de Herod, caede, p. 744. 
 
 Concerning this passage, see book iv. 
 0. 5. 
 
 '<> Phitarch. Aristid. 1. 
 
 '^ Corp. Inscript. Nos. 1579, 1580. 
 
 '=^ Aristot. PoUt. V. 5. 
 
 *^ Tayr) is the tax appointed to be 
 paid to the king. See the passage of
 
 300 
 
 THE DIFFERENT BRANCHES OF 
 
 [bk. 
 
 ol)tained should be disposed of. With regard to expenditure, 
 what branches should be retrenched, and at what time, and 
 whether the king should pay in money or in kind. The 
 economy of satraps comprehends six descriptions of revenues, 
 arising from land; from the peculiar products of the soil; from 
 places of trade'*; from duties {oltto reXcav) ; from cattle; and from 
 sundries. The first and best is the land tax, or tithe {eK(f)6piov^% 
 heKarn) ; the second is from gold, silver, brass, &c.; the third re- 
 lates to harbour dues and other port duties; the fourth compre- 
 hends tolls taken by land and at markets {airo tcov Kara yrjv re 
 Kol dyopaicov reXcov) ; the fifth the tax upon cattle, or the tithe 
 (iTTiKapTTia, BeKaTT)), by which we are not to understand the 
 money paid for the right of feeding cattle upon the public pas- 
 tures, but a duty upon the animals themselves; of which nature 
 was a tax collected by Dionysius the elder, tyrant of Syracuse, 
 with almost incredible harshness and effrontery^®; the sixth 
 item comprises a poll tax {eTTiKecpaXacov) and a tax upon 
 industry {xeopcoyd^cov). On the subject of the political eco- 
 nomy, which has particular reference to the question now under 
 consideration, the inaccurate author is very brief. He thinks 
 the best kind of revenue is in this case that derived from the 
 peculiar products of the country, mines therefore in particular; 
 also tolls levied in harbours, and duties of a similar descrip- 
 tion'^; and lastly, the receipts arising from the common things 
 (aTTo TCOV iyKUfc\LO)v) ; which expression, on account of its many 
 meanings, some have understood as referring to the census, 
 some to the ordinary liturgies, or have wished to remove the 
 difficulty by conjecture'^; but it evidently means the common 
 
 Hesyclnus in Schneider's prefaxje, p. 
 ix. The explanation there given by 
 the editor is in my opinion incorrect. 
 
 ** I read utto e/x7ropicoi/. 
 
 >* Cf. Lex. Seg. p. 24?. 
 
 ^^ The transaction is related at full 
 length in Tseud-Aristot. (Econ. 2, 20. 
 
 '^ Atto ffinopiw Koi 8i dyoypcou. 
 Tlie last words are evidently corrupt : 
 for to understand tlie public games, 
 because they were usually connected 
 
 with markets, is manifestly out of the 
 question. Ileeren (Ideen. vol. iii. p. 
 333) proposes dyopav; Schneider dyo- 
 paloiv ; but then hi.a must be omitted. 
 I conjecture Staycoywv, and understand 
 transit duties (Siaywytoi/, Polyb. iv. 
 52), which, from their not falling upon 
 the inhabitants, might occupy a very 
 high station in the Political Economy. 
 '" See particularly Schneider's pre- 
 face, whose conjecture, eyKTrjixdrcov, is
 
 CH. I.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 301 
 
 inland traffic of commodities, upon which indirect taxes were 
 imposed. In the same manner, in speaking subsequently of 
 the private economy, after having stated that the best revenue 
 is that which arises from the land, he mentions first the income 
 from the other common things (aTro tmv dWcov iyKVKXrjfjLaTwv), 
 that is, from the profits of trade, and afterwards the income 
 accruing from money placed out at interest. 
 
 It is upon the whole manifest from these observations, brief 
 and unconnected as they are, that revenues derived from public 
 property and indirect taxes, were considered as best adapted 
 for the political economy, to which the economy of the Greek 
 republics belongs. In how great a degree indirect taxes were 
 detrimental to morality, a subject which has been often dwelt 
 upon in modern times, the ancients were not aware; and 
 if these duties are moderate, as was the case in ancient 
 times, the amount of injury cannot be considerable. Man 
 always finds an opportunity for doing evil, and if one is 
 removed he will seek for another: the cause of virtue is ill 
 promoted by making vice impossible. On the other hand, 
 direct taxes imposed upon the soil, upon industry, or upon 
 persons, excepting only in cases of emergency, were looked upon 
 in Greece as despotic and arbitrary, it being considered as a 
 necessary element of freedom, that the property of the citizen, 
 as well as his occupation and person, should be exempt from all 
 taxation, excepting only when a free community taxed itself, 
 which power is obviously an essential part of liberty. The 
 most ignominious of all impositions was the poll tax, a tax paid 
 only by slaves to their tyrants*, or by the deputy of the slaves 
 to the satrap; or required from subjugated nations by their 
 conquerors: of this description were the taxes levied by the 
 
 extremely improbable. The Political 
 Economy is the public economy of cities, 
 which as such, and without reference 
 to satraps or kings, to whom they 
 might be subject, were free corpora- 
 tions : in these therefore the land tax 
 could not have been considered as one 
 of the best sources of revenue. In 
 
 addition to which he must also write 
 eyKTTjfxaTcov in the following part, 
 where it does not make any sense. 
 
 * [In Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 5, 
 it is stated that on one occasion the 
 Athenians at Potidaea, who had no 
 land, paid a poll tax of 2 minas a head. 
 — Transl.]
 
 302 
 
 THE PUBLIC REVENUE. 
 
 [bk, 
 
 III. 
 
 Romans upon the inhabitants of the provinces'". "As the 
 land," says Tertullian*'% " has less value if it is subject to an 
 impost, so are men more degraded if they pay a poll tax; for it 
 is a token of captivity." All persons who were not citizens of a 
 free state, were compelled either to pay a capitation tax, or to 
 forfeit their lives. When Condalus, appointed by Mausolus as 
 governor over the Lycians, a people who dehghted in wearing long 
 hair, ordered them to pay a poll tax, in case they failed to sup- 
 ply the king with sufficient materials for the false hair which he 
 pretended to want*', the demand was in reality most lenient. 
 With equal right he could have required their lives or money as 
 a substitute: for the Great King was sole possessor of the 
 persons of all his subjects. 
 
 Chapter II. 
 
 Rents accruing from Lands, Houses, and other immoveable 
 Property of the State and of Public Bodies. 
 
 The term duty [riXos) has sometimes a wider and sometimes a 
 more limited signification: almost every tax, with the exception 
 of the justice fees and fines, is denoted by this name. In this 
 place, where the liturgies and property taxes do not come into 
 consideration, we include under it all revenues arising from 
 the property of the state, from the custom duties levied in the 
 harbours and markets, and the taxes upon persons and industry. 
 All property was either in the hands of individuals, or 
 belonged to corporations, companies, temples, or to the state 
 itself. We also find that the property of certain temples 
 belonged to the demi; as, for example, the demus of Pireeus 
 was possessed of the theseum and other sacred lands; and the 
 state itself must also be considered as the owner of much sacred 
 property; so that sacred property and the property of the state 
 
 '* Cic. ad Attic, v. 16. 
 
 *" Tertull. Apolog. 13. The indic- 
 tion by capita, which from the time of 
 Diocletian, as it appears, and more 
 particularly after Constan tine the First, 
 
 caused great oppression in the Roman 
 empire, was not a poll tax, but a tax 
 upon landed property, cattle, and 
 slaves. 
 *' Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. 2, 14.
 
 CH. 
 
 I.] 
 
 RENTS OF THE STATE. 
 
 303 
 
 frequently coincide. But whatever may have been the right by 
 which sacred property of this description was held, the original 
 object for which the sacred demesnes (re/xeV?;) had been set 
 apart was retained, viz. that the sacrifices and the other expenses 
 should be defrayed out of the proceeds; for which purpose, 
 unless the cultivation of it was prohibited by some malediction, 
 it was always leased out^^ The property of the state and of the 
 corporations or temples consisted either in pastures for cattle, or 
 in forests, over which particular inspectors {vXcopol) were set^^, 
 or in tillage-land, houses, salt-works, water'*, mines, &c. : what 
 number of possessions of this kind belonged to the state of 
 Athens, besides the property of the temples and the several 
 corporations, it is impossible now to ascertain. The demesnes 
 which once belonged to the kings, cannot be supposed to have 
 come into the possession of the state after the abolition of the 
 kingly office; it is more probable that they remained the private 
 property of the royal family; much land indeed became the 
 property of the state by confiscation, conquest, and ancient pos- 
 session; but they frequently sold the confiscated, and lost the 
 conquered territory. 
 
 All property, both of corporations and of the state, as well 
 such as was sacred as such as was not [lepa koI ocna and 
 hrj^ocna), was leased out either permanently or for a term of 
 years; and the rent accruing to the state was made over to a 
 farmer-general. The latter fact is most distinctly seen from 
 the instance of Cephisius, mentioned by Andocides"^: this 
 
 -^ Harpocrat. in v. utto fxicrOoifidTcov^ 
 referring to Isocrat. Areopag. 1 1 . Ex- 
 amples of this occur in many inscrip- 
 tions. 
 
 23 Aristot. Polit. vi. 8. 
 
 2* An instance of sacred institutions 
 possessing property in water occurs in 
 Strabo xiii. p. 442, which refers to 
 Asia. At Byzantium the salt and 
 fisheries belonged to the state; at 
 Athens, in part at least, to the demi. 
 [The latter assertion appears to rest 
 upon an erroneous reading in an in- 
 scription ; see Note A at the end of the 
 
 book. — Transl.] 
 
 ■^^ De Myst. p. 45. Kr](f)Laios fxiu 
 ovTOcrl Trptdfiepos dovrjv €K tov drjfjLoaiov 
 Tas €K ravrqs iTTiKapirias twv iv rfj yrj 
 (scil. 8r]fj.o(rLa) yea>pyovvToov ivevqKovra 
 fxvds f/fXe^ay, ov aare^aXe rf] troKei Kai 
 e(})vy€V' el yap rjXOev, eSeSer' av iv rto 
 ^liKco' 6 yap v6p.os ovrtoseix^ Kvpiav eivai 
 TTjv [re] ^ovXtjV^bs av nptdpevos reXos p.r} 
 KaTo^akri, belv els to ^v\ov. The words 
 iv TTJ yfj have been suspected, but they 
 appear to be genuine; Sluiter's con- 
 jectures are wholly inadmissible.
 
 304 RENTS OF THE STATE, [bK. III. 
 
 person had taken a lease from the state, by virtue of which he 
 collected a tax of 90 minas from the cultivators of the public 
 lands, and was to pay over this money to the state. In like 
 manner a farmer of the pasturage money {vofMcovr]^, scrip- 
 turarius) existed in Orchomenus*% as well as in the Roman 
 empire, who collected the duty from individuals: the state, for 
 the sake of avoiding trouble, and of obviating the necessity of 
 any paid officers, collected none of its own revenues directly, 
 with the exception of the fines and the extraordinary war taxes; 
 whereas in the case of the property of temples and corporations, 
 the duty was never leased to a farmer-general. 
 
 At Athens the rent appears to have been usually fixed in 
 money; exceptions, however, occur in leases which were held 
 by the tenants on condition of paying a tithe, or of furnishing 
 certain sacrifices for a particular temple, and also in the case of 
 certain kinds of property which were burdened with an obli- 
 gation to pay a tax of a tenth to the state, probably because 
 they had originally been public property, and been transferred 
 to private individuals as usufructuary possessors; these tithes 
 of the produce were sold by the state to a farmer-general*^. We 
 find that in other countries besides Attica, payments of rent in 
 kind were of very frequent occurrence in ancient days. Thus, 
 for example, they occur in the Heraclean tables, which contain 
 a lease of the property of the temple of Bacchus and Minerva 
 Polias granted by the state. 
 
 The duration of leases was probably very unequal in different 
 cases; the Orchomenians, in an instance which has been pre- 
 served to our days, granted the usufructuary right to the public 
 pastures for a term of four years ; the demus of Piraeus let its 
 property for ten years. Upon the whole, however, we have not a 
 sufficient number of individual cases to enable us to draw any 
 general inference; for the number of accounts upon this ques- 
 tion which we now possess, is extremely scanty; and we have 
 
 ^ Corp. Iiiscript. No. 1569. Thu- | -^^ The only mention that I have as 
 cydides (v. 53) mentions that the Epi- j yet met with of a similar tax of a 
 daurians paid a duty of this kind to j tenth belonging to the state, occurs in 
 the I'ythian Apollo. ; Corp. Inscript. No. 76.
 
 CH. II.] 
 
 AND OF PUBLIC BODIES. 
 
 305 
 
 scarcely any information on the subject of lettings, except those 
 which regard the sacred property of the state. An example, in 
 addition to that quoted from Andocides, is given by ^Elian^% 
 who relates, that Athens had let the public domains of the 
 Euboean Chalcis, with the exception of the land dedicated to 
 Minerva, and necessarily of that which had been granted 
 to the cleruchi: the public documents of this transaction 
 were preserved at Athens in inscriptions set up in front of the 
 royal porch. 
 
 Over many possessions of this kind separate officers were 
 placed, as, for instance, the managers chosen from among the 
 Areopagites (iTnfieXrfral, iTnyvcofjuopes)^ who were appointed 
 to the care of the sacred olive-trees ffiopiac), the produce of 
 which was paid as a rent^^. According to Demosthenes^ % it 
 was the duty of the demarch to enforce payment of the rent for 
 the property of the temples ; this statement however doubtless 
 refers only to the property of the demi. Other rents were 
 received by officers employed by the state or the temples, 
 according as they arose either from public or sacred property. 
 As prior to the introduction of the demarchs, the naucrari per- 
 formed the duties of this office, we find that the exaction of the 
 public monies, as well as the letting of the public property, are 
 enumerated among their duties^'. 
 
 Xenophon expressly mentions houses among the tenements 
 which were rented from the state^^; the same description of 
 
 28 V. H. vi. I. It may be also 
 thought that the revenue from public 
 lands in Attica is signified in Thucyd. 
 vi. 91, by the words dno y^? ; but the 
 incomes received by private indivi- 
 duals from their estates may be under- 
 stood there with equal reason. 
 
 ■'^ Lys. Apolog. vnep tov cttjkov p. 
 260. Comp. Markland's notes, p. 269, 
 282. The decree of the Emperor Ha- 
 drian, with regard to the pajnnent of 
 the third or eighth part of the pro- 
 duce of the olive-trees (Corp. Inscript. 
 No. 355) refers not to public but to 
 private property, of which that part 
 
 was to be allotted to the public use, 
 and was of course to be paid for. It 
 is therefore a forced sale to the state 
 of Athens, as was the case in the 
 Roman empire with wine and com in 
 the time of the emperors. Cf. Bur- 
 mann. de Yectig. P. R. 3. 
 
 30 Cont. Eubulid. p. 1318, 20. 
 
 3^ Ammon. in v. vavKXrjpot, Phot, in 
 V. vavKpapoi. 
 
 2^ De Vectig. 4, repevrj, lepa, olKias. 
 The middle word is obscure. Might 
 not the revenue derived from the sa- 
 crifices have been let in farm, and been 
 signified by the word lepa l^sacra, tem- 
 X
 
 306 
 
 RENTS OF THE STATE, 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 property was also sometimes held by sacred corporations, and 
 let by them to tenants, having been in many cases derived from 
 free-gift or confiscation. Thus the temple of Apollo at Delos 
 let property of this kind together with its other domains"; and 
 other bodies probably did the same. The Mendeeans, says the 
 author of the (Economies' % applied the harbour duties and 
 other taxes to the uses of government ; the taxes on land and 
 houses they did not collect, but kept an account of those who 
 possessed such property ; and when there was a want of sup- 
 plies, they raised it from these debtors, who profited by this 
 indulgence, having had the use of the money in the mean time, 
 without paying any interest. From this it has been inferred 
 that both a land and a house tax existed; but it is evident that 
 the writer only means the public lands which were held in lease 
 from the state, and that the rent was left unpaid without interest, 
 in order that a fund might accumulate which could be used on 
 occasion of need, and at the same time a greater profit be allowed 
 to the tenants. It may be moreover observed that the houses 
 at Athens were let to contractors {vavKXypoc) ; which name also 
 signifies landlords [a-raOfiovxoi) ; for they afterwards sublet the 
 houses to lodgers, in the same manner as private proprietors". 
 This is probably the meaning of the singular expression of the 
 grammarians^^ who state, that persons were called by the same 
 appellation [vavKkTjpoi), who were hired to attend to the collec- 
 tion of the house-rent. The truth is, that the subletting was 
 transferred to them as contractors, from which they obtained 
 their profit, and so far they might be considered as hired ser- 
 vants of the proprietor. It has been already remarked that the 
 tenants of houses paid their rent to the state by prytaneas, and 
 not by the month^^; whether however in every prytanea, or 
 only in some prytaneas, as the other farmers of duties, I will 
 not attempt to decide. 
 
 All these lands were let by auction to the highest bidder; and 
 
 pies or sacrifices) ? At least the theatre 
 was let out in this manner, which to a 
 certain point was sacred property. 
 
 88 Corp. Inscript. No. 158, § 4. 
 
 »< 2, 21, ed. Schneid. 
 
 3' Comp. above book i. ch. 24. 
 3* Harpocrat. Suid. Amnion. Lex. 
 Seg. p. 282, &c. 
 37 i. 24.
 
 CH. If.] AND OF PUBLIC BODIES. 30? 
 
 for this purpose the conditions of lease were previously engraved 
 upon stone, and fixed up in public. The names of the lessees 
 could be subsequently added ; so that the document which had 
 been originally exhibited then became a lease, or, if not, a fresh 
 agreement was afterwards set up. 
 
 A notice or advertisement, the date of which is either Olymp. 
 114, 4, or 115, 3 (b.c. 321 or 318), mutilated at the end, by 
 which the demus Piraeus offers some property to be let, may, 
 as far as it is intelligible, be translated nearly word for word as 
 fbllows'«. 
 
 ^^ In the Archonship of Archippus, Phrynion being Demarch, 
 
 '^ The Pireeans let Paralia and Halmyris and the Theseum 
 and all the other sacred lands, upon the following conditions. 
 That the tenants for more than 10 drachmas are to give suffi- 
 cient security for the payment of the rent, and those for less 
 than 10 drachmas are to provide a surety, whose property shall 
 be liable for the same. Upon these conditions they let the 
 lands tax and duty free. And if any property-tax be imposed 
 upon the farms according to their valuation, the burghers will 
 pay it. The tenants shall not be allowed to remove wood or 
 earth from the Theseum and the other sacred lands, nor [da- 
 mage] whatever wood there is in the farm. The tenants of the 
 Thesmophorium and the Schoenus and the other pasture lands, 
 shall pay half the rent in Hecatombceon (the first month), and 
 the other half in Posideon (the sixth month). The tenants 
 occupying Paralia and Halmyris and the Theseum, and any 
 other grounds that there may be, shall cultivate them for the 
 first nine years in whatever manner they please, and is accord- 
 ing to custom ; but in the tenth year they shall plough the half 
 of the land, and no more, so that the succeeding tenant will be 
 able to begin preparing the soil from the 16th of Anthesterion 
 And if he shall plough more than half, the excess of the produce 
 shall be the property of the burghers/^ After this there fol- 
 lows a stipulation that the tenant shall receive a house con- 
 nected with one of the farms in good repair. 
 
 In another fragment containing conditions of lease, in one 
 
 2^ See Note A at the end of the book. 
 
 X 2
 
 308 
 
 RENTS OF THE STATE, AND OF PUBLIC BODIES. [bK. III. 
 
 of which a tribe proposes to let some lands, probably sacred 
 lands'% the payment of the rent is divided into three instal- 
 ments, at the beginning of the year, in the seventh and in the 
 eleventh month. The theatres were let in the same manner as 
 landed property, a proof of which is given in another Pirsean 
 inscription^". According to this document, the lessee of the 
 theatre is bound to keep the building in proper repair, for which 
 reason he is called the chief architect''^; his receipts were doubt- 
 less derived from the entrance-money of such citizens as were 
 furnished with it by the state, and of all aliens, who had not, like 
 the ambassadors, free admission. The rent paid by the tenant 
 of the theatre of Piraeus, was, in the instance which has come 
 down to us, 3300 drachmas : the demus of Pireeus, as owner 
 of the theatre, presents with crowns the lessees and a person 
 named Theiseus, who had succeeded in increasing the rent by 
 300 drachmas'*. 
 
 Another item deserving of mention is the money bearing 
 interest, which not the state only, but temples, and perhaps also 
 corporations, were possessed of. Thus from the funds belong- 
 ing to the Delian Apollo, large sums of money had been lent to 
 states, and bankers, or other private individuals"^; some Corcy- 
 rsean nobles consecrated a considerable sum for sacred uses, that 
 the interest which it produced might be expended in the cele- 
 bration of games to Bacchus'**; and the temple of Delphi also 
 appears, according to Demosthenes, to have lent out some of 
 the sacred money "^. 
 
 8» Corp. Inscript. No. 104. 
 ''<' Corp. Inscript. No. 102. 
 ■" Comp. above book ii. ch. 13. 
 
 500, and CEnophon with 1100 drach- 
 mas. 
 
 ■•^ Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 
 *'^ At the end of the inscription the j ''^ Coi-p. Inscript. No. 1845. 
 
 names of the farmers, and how much 
 each gave, are mentioned : the uivrjToi 
 are, Aristophanes with 600 drachmas, 
 Melesias with 1100, Arethusius with 
 
 ••= Demosth, c. ]Mid. p. 561, in the 
 account of the Alcraaeonidae. Of this 
 fact, however, Herodotus (v. 62 sqq.) 
 knew nothing.
 
 CH. 111.] REVENUE FROM MINES OF THE STATE. 309 
 
 Chapter III. 
 
 Revenue arising from the Mines of the State, 
 
 The mines {ixeraWa) belonging to the state of Athens were 
 partly native and partly foreign. 
 
 The former were the silver mines of Laurium*% from which 
 the nation derived very considerable advantages, as by their 
 means Themistocles first raised the naval force of Athens to a 
 state of importance. They extended from coast to coast, in a 
 line of seven EngUsh miles, from Anaphlystus to Thoricus. 
 The working of them had been commenced at an early period, 
 and it appears to have been very profitable in the time of The- 
 mistocles; they had however become less productive in the age 
 of Socrates and Xenophon, and before the age of Strabo had 
 been so entirely exhausted, that in his time they only used the 
 earth which had been previously extracted, together with the 
 old scoriae, and all farther mining was discontinued. The ores 
 contained silver and lead, with zinc, and possibly copper ; but 
 no gold, at least not enough to allow the ancients, mth their 
 imperfect processes of separation, to have extracted it with 
 profit. At Thoricus spurious emeralds occurred in combination 
 with the ore ; also the cinnabar, which was found there, and the 
 Athenian sil, a substance much prized for dyeing, were equally 
 valuable. The mines were worked with shafts and adits, and by 
 the removal of whole masses, so that supports alone {fjueaoKpivels;) 
 were left standing. The processes of fusion carried on in the 
 furnaces appear, upon the whole, to have been the same as those 
 employed in the other mines which were worked in ancient 
 times. The people or the state was sole proprietor of the mines; 
 but they were never worked at the public expense, nor did the 
 state ever let them for a term of years, like other landed pro- 
 perty; portions of them were sold or demised to individuals 
 with the reservation of a perpetual rent, and these leases were 
 
 ■*® See the Dissertation on the Silver Mines of Laiirion^ [at the end of the 
 volume.]
 
 310 REVENUE ARISING FROM [bK. III. 
 
 transferred from one person to another by inheritance, sale, and 
 every kind of legal conveyance. The sale of the mines (that is, 
 of the right of working them) was managed by the poletce ; this 
 right was purchased at an appointed price, in addition to which 
 the possessor paid the twenty-fourth part of the net produce as 
 a perpetual tax. The purchase-money was paid directly to the 
 state; the metal rents were in all probability let to a farmer- 
 general. The amount of the money obtained from both sources 
 (to which must also be added a small income accruing to the 
 state from the market and the public buildings,) necessarily 
 depended on a variety of circumstances ; such for example as 
 the number of mines let in the course of the year, the compara- 
 tive richness or poverty of the veins discovered, or the degree of 
 activity with which the mining was carried on. In the time of 
 Socrates, these mines produced less than at an earlier period : 
 when Themistocles proposed to the Athenians to apply the 
 money accruing from the mines to the building of ships, instead 
 of dividing it, as before, among the people, the annual receipts 
 appear to have amounted to 30 or 40 talents; although the 
 accounts relating to this point are extremely obscure and uncer- 
 tain. Citizens and isoteles were alone entitled to the posses- 
 sion of mines. The number of the possessors was evidently 
 considerable ; and, like the agriculturists, they were considered 
 as a separate class of producers ; sometimes they possessed 
 several shares, sometimes only one. The common price of a 
 single share was a talent, or rather more; occasionally several 
 partners occur as the joint possessors of a mine. The manual 
 labour was performed by slaves, either belonging to the pos- 
 sessors of the mines or hired; the slaves thus employed by the 
 mine-proprietors were extremely numerous, and although the 
 cheapness of their labour diminished the expenses of mining, the 
 improvements of art in facilitating and abridging the processes 
 of labour were retarded. The security of this possession was 
 firmly guaranteed by severe laws ; and the rights of the state 
 were strictly maintained. There was a mining law {fjL6raWcK6<; 
 vofjLos), and a peculiar course of legal proceedings in cases relat- 
 ing to mines (BUao fieTaWtKal), which, for the greater encou- 
 ragement of the mine-proprietors, were in the time of Demos-
 
 CH. III.] 
 
 THE MINES OF THE STATE. 
 
 311 
 
 thenes annexed to the monthly suits. The mines were also free 
 from property taxes, and did not subject the possessor to the 
 performance of liturgies, nor were they transferred in the avri- 
 So<rt9, or exchange of property; immunities, which did not 
 arise from any wish to encourage the working of mines, but 
 were founded upon the nature of their tenure from the state ; 
 for they were considered as public property let to usufructuary 
 possessors in consideration of a fixed rate of payment, like the 
 duties paid by the farmers ; and no property which was not 
 freehold, and exempt from rent or duty, subjected the posses- 
 sor to liturgies and property taxes. 
 
 In what manner the stone quarries were regulated, in which 
 the finest varieties of marble were found*'', and which by the 
 ancients*^ were also considered as mines, I have been unable to 
 ascertain. 
 
 That Athens usurped possession of the mines of her subject 
 allies, cannot be assumed in conformity with the whole system 
 of her foreign policy: we must suppose that they everywhere 
 remained the property of the persons to whom they had belonged 
 previously to the dominion of Athens. 
 
 The mines in Thrace appear however to form an exception, 
 and to have been immediately dependent upon Athens; it is 
 probable that they were let in the same manner as the Athenian 
 mines, although we have no certain information as to this point. 
 The Thracian gold mines had been first worked by the Phoeni- 
 cians, together with the mines of Thasos, and afterwards by the 
 Thasians of Paros. The gold mines of Scapte Hyle upon the 
 main-land brought to the state of Thasos an annual revenue of 
 80 talents. Those of Thasos were less productive; but they 
 yielded so large a sum, that the Thasians, with a complete free- 
 dom from all land-taxes, derived from the mines of the island 
 and of the continent, together with the custom duties collected 
 in the harbours, and perhaps the rents of some lands in Thrace, 
 an annual income of 200 or 300 talents*^ When the Athenians 
 
 *' Caryophilus de Marmoribus p. 4 
 sqq. 
 
 ^« E. g. Strab. ix. p. 275; Pollux 
 
 vii. 100. 
 
 4» So Herodotus vi. 46*, must be un- 
 derstood.
 
 312 
 
 REVENUE FROM MINES OF THE STATE. [bK. HI. 
 
 had established themselves in Thrace, they entered into a contest 
 with the Thasians for the possession of the mines and harbours 
 of the main-land. Cimon captured 33 of their ships in a naval 
 engagement, besieged and reduced the city, and gained for his 
 country the coast, together with the gold mines*". Thus the 
 Athenians obtained possession not only of Scapte Hyle, but 
 also of other cities on the main-land, for which, as belonging to 
 the Thasians, these islanders had, in the expedition of Xerxes, 
 borne the expense of provisioning his army*': Stryme also, a 
 Thasian commercial town", may be referred to this number, for 
 which, when the power of Athens in those regions was broken, 
 Thasos contended with Maronea*^; doubtless also Galepsus and 
 CEsyme, colonies of the Thasians**; likewise Datum, which was 
 also a Thasian town, situated between Neapolis and Nestos, 
 where the Athenians, at the same time that the battle against 
 Thasos took place (Olymp. 79^ 1? b. c. 463), fought with the 
 Edoni for the possession of the gold mines'*. Crenides how- 
 ever does not appear to have belonged to the Thasians in early 
 times, although this town was under their dominion in the 
 105th Olympiad (b.c. 360). It is highly probable that the 
 Athenians at this time, as Thasos had before them, received 
 the revenues of all these towns, as well as of the gold mines : 
 the latter were perhaps partly granted to Athenian tenants, 
 while some of the ancient possessors remained in undisturbed 
 occupation. If as many names of proprietors of the Thracian, 
 as of the Laurian mines, had been preserved, we should be able 
 to speak wath more certainty on this point; but the extent of 
 our knowledge is, that Thucydides was possessed of gold mines 
 in Thrace*^ Even, however, with regard to Thucydides, it 
 remains doubtful in what manner he became possessed of them. 
 If they were situated at Scapte Hyle (at which place Thucy- 
 dides lived, wrote, and died in exile*', after it had passed from 
 
 *" Plutarch. Cim. 14; Thucyd. i. 
 100, 101; Diod. xi. 70. 
 *' Herod, vii. 18. 
 »^ Herod, vii. 118; Suid. in. v. 
 
 " The Epistle of Philip in the Ora- 
 tion attributed to Demosthenes. 
 
 *^ Thuc. iv. 107. Concerning Ga- 
 lepsus comp. also v. 6. 
 
 " Herod, ix. 75; cf. Thuc. i. 100, 
 iv. 102 ; Diod. xi. 70 ; xii. 68; Pausan. 
 i. 29, 4. 
 
 *« Thuc. iv. 105. 
 
 ^' Plutarch. Cim. 4, and in the
 
 CH. IV.] THE CUSTOM DUTIES. 313 
 
 under the dominion of Athens), they could not have made part 
 of the inheritance of Hegesipyle, the daughter of the king of 
 Thrace*% from whom Thucydides was descended; for Scapte 
 Hyle belonged not to Thrace, but to Thasos: it is more pro- 
 bable that they were derived from Athens, after Cimon, Thucy- 
 dides' near relation, had conquered the Thasian territory: but 
 the account most deserving of credit, is, that Thucydides 
 obtained them by marriage with an inhabitant of Scapte Hyle, 
 whose predecessors had been perhaps long in possession of 
 them'^ 
 
 Chapter IV. 
 
 The Custom Duties, and particularly the Duty of the Fiftieth, 
 or Two per Cent, 
 
 The custom duties were partly raised from the harbours, 
 partly from the markets [air ifjuTropiov koL dyopd<i). The 
 former word signified the places for wholesale trade in com- 
 modities carried by sea, and the taxes there raised were custom 
 duties upon exports and imports together with certain fees paid 
 for foreign ships lying in the harbour. The markets were 
 attended by the countrymen and retail-dealers {dyopaloL, KaTrrj- 
 \ot), and the revenues derived from these are the taxes upon 
 the sale of goods consumed in the country, and the fees paid 
 for the right of selling in the market^". The latter were pro- 
 bably paid by aliens only, the citizens having liberty to sell 
 
 Essay de Exilio, Marcelliims' Life of 
 Thucydides, p. 724, 729, in the gi-eat 
 Leipsig edition of Thucydides. 
 
 ^8 This is the opinion of Phitarch 
 and Marcellinus, p. 722, although the 
 contrary statement occurs in the latter 
 Avriter, the life which bears his name 
 being a mixture of different accoimts. 
 Hegesipyle was the wife of Miltiades 
 the younger. 
 
 ^^ Marcellin. p. 723. 'Hyayero de 
 yvvniKa dno SKOTrr^ff vXrjs rTJs OpoKrjs 
 TrXovcriav cr(j)6bpa Kai fxiraXXa kckti]- 
 HfUTjv iv TT) OpaKj], 
 
 ^" Upon the difference between 
 merchants {efiTropoi) and retail dealers 
 Salmasius treats at full length in liis 
 Book de Usuris. I only mention one 
 important passage, Plat, de Repub. ii. 
 p. 370 E, sqq. Whether there were 
 really two kinds of empoiia, for fo- 
 reigners and natives {^eviKov and 
 daTLKov), as is stated in Lex. Seg. p. 
 208, seems to me doubtful. In the 
 same Lexicon, p. 255, in v. eVt/zeXjyrat, 
 'Attckov should be restored from Har- 
 pocration. 'E/x7ropioi/ ^Attikov fre- 
 quently occurs in Demosthenes.
 
 314 
 
 THE CUSTOM DUTIES. 
 
 QbK. III. 
 
 their goods there without being subject to any tax. An exemp- 
 tion from the custom duties was also granted in some instances 
 to private individuals, probably however only for their own 
 consumption; and the persons who possessed it must have 
 been very few in number, for Demosthenes asserts in general of 
 the immunity from duties {aTeXeia) that it detracted nothing 
 from the public revenue, whereas if it had been given to many 
 persons, it must have considerably diminished the rent derived 
 from this source^'. In addition to these taxes, all imports 
 and exports were subject to a small duty of 2 per cent., or 
 the fiftieth {irevTr^KoaTrj) ; the grammarians^* state expressly 
 that all commodities imported into the Pirseus from foreign 
 countries were subject to this duty: that this was the case with 
 imported corn, and manufactured commodities, such as woollen 
 garments, drinking- cups, and other vessels, we know for certain 
 from ancient writers^^; that it was paid upon exported cattle, 
 and even on such as belonged to an Athenian theoria, we learn 
 from the Sandwich inscription^*: and if the fiftieth had not 
 been laid upon all exports, how could Demosthenes have referred 
 to the books of the pentecostologi, to prove that the cargo 
 of a ship which had cleared out from Athens, was only worth 
 5500 drachmas"? Ulpian^' affirms that arms were imported 
 duty free; an assertion which is doubtless correct, if we under- 
 stand it to refer only to arms which the soldiers used for pur- 
 poses of war, but can hardly be true of those which were 
 imported as saleable commodities; Ulpian^s testimonies gene- 
 rally prove nothing, for they are merely inferences from pas- 
 sages of Demosthenes which he misunderstood. Concerning 
 the import and export by land, I have met with nothing except 
 a passage which will be mentioned presently; they cannot 
 
 8' Demosth. in Lept. § 21, ed. Wolf. 
 Concerning the exemption from cus- 
 tom duties see also book i. ch. 15. 
 
 ^'^ Etymol. in v. TTevTrjKotrTokoyov- 
 ficpov, Lex. Seg. p. 297 ; Lex. Seg. p. 
 192,30. Neither llarpocration, Pol- 
 hix, nor Photius, liave any thing of 
 in)portajice on the fiftieth. 
 
 «3 Orat. 0. Neaer. p. 1353, 23; De- 
 mosth. c. Mid. p. 558, 16. 
 
 ^* Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 
 ^5 Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 909. The 
 export duty is called napayayiov in 
 Philippides the comic poet, Pollux ix. 
 90. [Mein.Fr. Com. Gr. vol. iv., p. 472.] 
 
 •^^ Ad Demosth. c. Mid. ut sup.
 
 CH. 
 
 IV.] 
 
 THE CUSTOM DUTIES. 
 
 315 
 
 indeed have been considerable; for in Greece, and Athens in 
 particular, the intercourse with other states was chiefly carried 
 on by sea. The duty was paid upon imported commodities at 
 the unlading®^: and upon exported commodities probably at the 
 shipping; it was collected by the pentecostologi, who have been 
 mentioned already*^ in money and not in kind, as is proved by 
 the Sandwich inscription, and by the circumstance that the 
 value of the commodities was entered in the books of the custom 
 duties. As the duty upon corn {TrevTijfcoa-TT) rov <tItov), 
 which was only imposed at the importation, was leased out to 
 individuals,^^ the fiftieth must have been sold in separate lots to 
 several farmers, according to some very general distinction of 
 the commodities. 
 
 To ascertain what sum the state annually received from the 
 fiftieth, is a problem of difficult solution. If the imported corn 
 amounted annually to about a million medimni, as has been 
 assumed in a former part of this work*; and if the price of a 
 medimnus is taken upon an average at 3 drachmas (although it 
 is not known upon what principles the custom-house valuation 
 was made), the farmer of the corn duty received 10 talents a 
 year, of which a part must be deducted for his trouble, the 
 expense of collection, and profit. 
 
 With regard to other commodities little information can be 
 afforded. The only passage on the amount of the fiftieth occurs 
 in the speech of Andocides concerning the mysteries '% but it 
 
 ^^ Demosth. Paragr. c. Lacrit. p. 
 932, 25 sqq. Plant. Trinumm. iv. 4, 15, 
 where however the Roman custom 
 may be meant. 
 
 *^ Besides other passages already 
 quoted with a different view, compare 
 upon this point A then. ii. p. 49 C. 
 
 *^ Orat. c. Neser. ut sup. 
 
 * Book i. ch. 15. 
 
 '^^ P. 65 sqq. This passage has for 
 the most part been rightly corrected 
 by Reiske. Cf. Valck. Diat. Eurip. 
 p. 293, and Sluiter's Lect. Andocid. p. 
 158 sqq. Agyrrhius must evidently 
 be read instead of Argyrius; apxaav 
 
 els should be altered to apx^vi^s, and 
 then write fxerea-xov d* aira and XevKtjv. 
 ToTTos is manifestly a gloss, and should 
 be omitted, and read ouy, and then 
 oXiyov for oXiyov from the Breslau 
 MS. The words (wy ttoWov a^iov are an 
 interpretation of oFov, and they appear 
 to me to be a gloss. Concerning yva>vai 
 I will not decide. I believe however 
 that it might be underetood if taken for 
 eScrrc yvSivat, j if not, axxre must be 
 added, or the word be altered to yvovres. 
 'Anekda-as koL I would alter with 
 Reiske into dniKatras Se, a various 
 reading, which Sluiter quotes from a
 
 316 
 
 THE CUSTOM DUTIES. 
 
 [bK. 111. 
 
 admits of so much doubt in the interpretation, that it will be 
 better to let him speak in his own words. " For this Agyr- 
 rhius, this model of excellence, was two years ago chief farmer of 
 the fiftieth, which he purchased for 30 talents; and all those 
 persons who were collected round him under the white poplar, 
 had a share in the concern. Upon their characters it is unne- 
 cessary for me to make any comment. Their object in assem- 
 bling there was, as far as I can judge, both to receive money for 
 not bidding higher, and to have a share in the profits, when the 
 duty was sold under its proper price. Aftenvards when they 
 liad gained 2 talents, and discovered that the concern was of 
 considerable value, they all combined together, and, giving the 
 others a share, they purchased the same duty for 30 talents; 
 then, as no one offered a higher sum, I myself went to the 
 senate, and bid against them, until I obtained it for- 36 talents. 
 Then having driven away these persons, and provided sureties 
 for myself, I collected the required sum, and paid it to the 
 state: nor was I a loser by the speculation, for the sharers in it 
 even made a small profit. Thus I was the means of preventing 
 these persons from dividing among themselves 6 talents of the 
 public money .^^ According to this account the lease was taken 
 by companies: Agyrrhius, and afterwards Andocides, had an 
 association of this kind: at the head of each company there 
 was a chief farmer {ap^covij^), by whose name it was called. It 
 was sold to the highest bidder by the poletee, with the proviso 
 of the approbation of the senate, near the white poplar tree: in 
 
 manuscript, and is also the reading of 
 the Breslau MS. Lastly, /xei/ should 
 be added after ^pax^a from the Bres- 
 lau MS., and the colon after fieraa- 
 Xoin-es changed into a comma. 'Apx<iivr}s 
 lias passed into the grammarians from 
 this passage. Etymol. and Lex. Seg. 
 p. 202. ^Apxoivrjs, 6 cipxcov wvrjs OVTI- 
 voaovu scil. Trpdy/xaroy, for example 
 TfXovs. llesychius ^Apxoovq^' 6 Trporj- 
 yovp-fvos cpyoXdjSojv, as has been rightly 
 corrected. To this also the neuTTjKoa- 
 rapxos belongs (as a friend has cor- 
 lectcd for nfVTTjKouTupx^^s) iii Lex. Seg. 
 
 p. 297j O apXfOV TTJS TTeVTrjKOCTTrjS TOV 
 
 reXovs Koi tcov TrevTrjKocTTcciv (1. TrevTrj- 
 KocTTcovcov). Cf. Phot. p. 301. With 
 regard to the emendation afterwards 
 proposed in the text of l| for hvo, which 
 was first edited by Reiske, it may be 
 observed that it is confirmed by Slui- 
 ter's and the Breslau MS., which read 
 Tpia for bvo : it was no doubt originally 
 written TI, from which II and III could 
 easily be derived [Tpi'a is also the 
 reading of four manuscripts collated 
 by Bekker, Orat. Alt. vol. i. p. 142.]
 
 CH. I.J THE CUSTOM DUTIES. 3l7 
 
 this instance however it was not the tax on any particular com- 
 modity, but the fiftieth in general, which therefore these persons 
 had on this occasion farmed in one lot, and not divided into 
 separate portions. Agyrrhius held the lease in the third year 
 before the delivery of the speech; Andocides received it in the 
 following year, for he took it from Agyrrhius, and in the next 
 succeeding year was involved by the party of this person in the 
 law suit concerning the mysteries. It has been incorrectly 
 supposed, that a three years' lease is intended, a meaning of 
 which the expression of the writer does not admit'^^ Andocides 
 indeed says, according to the present reading, that Agyrrhius 
 and his company had made a profit of 2 talents: he himself 
 offered 6 talents more than the former company; but unless he 
 wished to expose himself to evident loss, the highest offer he 
 could make, was what the company of Agyrrhius had paid and 
 gained at the former letting. From this it might be supposed, 
 that these 2 talents were an annual profit; and that the com- 
 pany of Agyrrhius had gained 6 talents in three years, with a 
 rent of 30 talents, which in that case must have been a three 
 years' rent; for Andocides states that the three years' profit 
 upon this rent, was as much as 36 talents. But, not to men- 
 tion that the idiom of the language compels us to understand a 
 letting which was taken for the third year before the delivery of 
 the speech, and not a three years' lease, it is not possible that 
 an orator should have made use of such inaccurate language, as 
 to state the rent for three years, and the profit of the lessee only 
 for one, without marking the difference. It is better to correct 
 the number, which is for other reasons uncertain, and to sup- 
 pose that the profit of the company of Agyrrhius was 6 talents 
 instead of 2. Moreover, if this profit and the rent were for 
 three years, the fiftieth would be extraordinarily low, particu- 
 larly when we consider the export of corn, although even this 
 did not compose the largest part of the whole receipts; the 
 other exports and imports, of cattle and other necessaries, salt 
 
 '^ De Pauw (Reclierches Philos. 
 vol. i. p. 356) understood it to mean a 
 rent for three yeara; Manso (Sparta, 
 
 vol. ii. p. 504) for one year. Tpirov eras 
 means the third year before, or /tw "years 
 ago.
 
 318 THE CUSTOM DUTIES. [bK. III. 
 
 fish and flesh, oil, wine, honey, hides, leather, wood, metals, 
 vessels, ointment, rigging, and other kinds of raw and manu- 
 factured commodities, would have far exceeded the amount of 
 the duty upon corn: the slaves also must have produced a con- 
 siderable sum, upon whom, as was the case in the Roman 
 customs, an import duty was also levied^^ And if the fiftieth, 
 inclusive of the cost of collection, only produced about 14 
 talents a year, the value of the commodities imported and 
 exported could not have amounted to more than 700 talents, 
 which is evidently too small a sum. In addition to this, the 
 only duty of which we know with certainty the duration of the 
 lease, viz. the tax upon prostitutes, was only let for a term of 
 one year. We must therefore suppose, that the same was the 
 case with the general letting of the other duties, and assume, 
 according to the words of Andocides himself, that the fiftieth 
 produced to the state from 30 to 36 talents a year; so that the 
 imports and exports, allowing for the profit of the letting and 
 the cost of collection, amounted to about 2000 talents'^ It 
 must however be remembered, that at this period Athens was 
 not in a flourishing condition, as it was the first years after the 
 anarchy : in prosperous times the custom duties were probably 
 far more productive. 
 
 In several other countries the custom duties were equally 
 considerable, and in some places they yielded a much larger 
 sum. In Macedonia the harbour duty was generally let for 20 
 talents; Callistratus raised the rent to 40 talents, by lessening 
 the amount of security; for whereas before his time, each 
 person was obliged to furnish security amounting at the lowest 
 to a talent, which none but the wealthy were able to procure, 
 he permitted the farmer to give security only for the third part, 
 or for whatever smallest portion of his rent he could persuade 
 the people to accept security^*. Can there be any doubt that a 
 yearly lease is here meant? The harbour duty of Rhodes 
 amounted before Olymp. 153, 4 (b.c. 165) to a million drachmas 
 
 ''^ Lex. Seg. p. 297, 21 , I exports not very differently at ten mil- 
 
 '^ Barth^lemy (Anacharsis, vol. iv. lions of livres. 
 p. 505) reckons the annual imports and ' ^* Aristot. CEcon. 2, 22.
 
 CH. IV.] THE CUSTOM DUTIES. ^19 
 
 (166 talents) a year: after it had considerably fallen off, it still 
 amounted to 150,000 drachmas (25 talents)". Cersocleptes of 
 Thrace received an annual income of 300 talents from the 
 harbour duties, at times when commerce was not impeded^^. 
 
 Whether Athens collected port duties in other countries, 
 for example, in the harbours of Thasos, which she had obtained 
 by conquest, or whether they were transferred to the states of 
 the cleruchi, I am unable to decide. On the other hand, 
 custom duties must necessarily have been established by land 
 against Megaris and Boeotia; for at certain times a total pro- 
 hibition existed against those countries: nothing determinate 
 can however be ascertained. It is related of Oropus, upon the 
 boundaries of Attica and Boeotia", that the inhabitants were all 
 plunderers and toll gatherers, and also raised a duty upon im- 
 ported goods, being men of the most immoderate avarice. This 
 might certainly be referred to a duty paid upon entrance into 
 the country, which the Boeotians and the Athenians had at 
 different times collected at this spot: but as Oropus was 
 situated on the sea, and as the importation from Euboea into 
 Attica originally went by way of Oropus, the meaning remains 
 uncertain. 
 
 Chapter V. 
 
 The Harbour Duties, and the Duty of a Hundredth, orOneperCent, 
 The Market Tolls. 
 
 In addition to the fiftieth which was imposed upon imports and 
 exports, it is probable that a separate duty was levied upon all 
 vessels (whether they were unladen or not) for the use of the 
 harbours, which had caused so large an expense to Athens ; as 
 we know that a duty was collected for permission to deposit 
 commodities in the warehouses and magazines^°. A harbour 
 
 '* Polyb. xxxi. 7, 12. | Com. Gr. vol. iv. p. 596. — Trans l.] 
 
 7« Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 657, 9. ! ^^ From Xenophon's proposals (de 
 '' Dicaearchus in the Description of Vectig.3,) we are justified in assuming 
 
 Greece, and the verses of Xenon which that this was the usual custom. 
 
 he has preserved. [See Meineke, Fr. ■
 
 320 
 
 THE HARBOUR DUTIES. 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 duty (iXkLfievcov) and collectors of the harbour duty (iWifMevta- 
 ral) are often mentioned. The latter, however, appear to have 
 been considered by Pollux^' as identical with the pentecosto- 
 logi. The pentecostologi at Athens, like the collectors of the 
 harbour duties in the Bosporus and elsewhere, and the Roman 
 portitores, examined the goods, valued them, and entered them 
 in their books^" : the term harbour duty is however a general 
 expression, which also comprehends import and export duties^ 
 as in the case of the harbour duty of the Rhodians. Neverthe- 
 less this fact does not prove that a separate duty was not im- 
 posed for the use of the harbour. I am induced to assume the 
 reality of such an impost, by two apparent traces of its exist- 
 ence. In a fragment of Eupolis^', a harbour duty is mentioned 
 which was to paid before the passenger embarked: it thus 
 appears that a duty was imposed in the harbour, even upon 
 individuals. In Xenophon's Essay upon the State of Athens^% 
 
 7^ viii. 132. Other passages in the | 
 grammarians, e. g. Lex. Seg. p. 251, 
 give no definite information concerning ; 
 the ellimenistse. 
 
 «" Demosth. c. Phorm. p. 917, 10, 
 cf. Jul. Afric. Cest. p. 304. 
 
 81 Ap. Poll. ix. 30. 'EXKifxeviov, 6 
 dovvai npiv elcr^r)vai ere Sei. 'Eta^rjvai 
 can evidently be only understood of 
 going on board a ship, as KUhn has 
 already remarked. 
 
 8^ i. 17. Sclmeider (Opuscul. Xe- 
 noph. p. 93) considers this hundredth to 
 be a custom duty, which was after- 
 wai-ds succeeded by the twentieth. 
 Neither to this notion however, nor to 
 that of Manso (Sparta, vol. ii. p. 496), 
 can I accede. With regard to the 
 twentieth, of which I have given the 
 true explanation in chap. 6, Manso 
 (p. 502) understands it to be an in- 
 creased custom duty upon commo- 
 dities levied in the Piraeus ; he com- 
 bines however passages wliich have 
 no reference to one another. Among 
 other things, lie assumes that the 
 Athenians only remitted to the allies 
 tliat part of the tribute wliich was in- 
 
 creased by Alcibiades, which he incor- 
 rectly states at 300 talents, and that 
 instead of it, a custom duty was col- 
 lected in the Piraeus. This duty was 
 not however levied upon the allies 
 alone, but upon all traders, whether 
 Athenians, allies, or not ; and who 
 compelled the allies to come to the Pi- 
 raeus with their commodities ? Athens 
 would manifestly by this increased 
 duty in the Piraeus have injured her 
 own imports, and raised the prices of 
 commodities, which would have been 
 against her own interest. The twen- 
 tieth was not collected in the Piraeus, but 
 in the countries of the allies. Manso 
 again, proceeding upon the amount of 
 the fiftieth, calculates the increased 
 duty at 90 talents : but is it conceiv- 
 able that the Athenians would have 
 established a duty producing only 90 
 talents, part of which moreover was 
 before received, instead of the tributes 
 which brought in so large an income, 
 in order to increase their revenues, 
 and yet, while it caused a precisely 
 opposite effect, have allowed the twen- 
 tieth to exist for so long a period?
 
 CH. v.] 
 
 THE HARBOUR DUTIES. 
 
 321 
 
 it is remarked that the necessity of trying their causes in Athens, 
 
 to which the aUies were subject, increased the productiveness of 
 the hundredth (exaToarr]) in the Piraeus. We are not justihed 
 
 Enough however of these errors. I 
 may observe that with this a main 
 argument of Schneider's falls to the 
 ground, that the Treatise upon the 
 State of Athens is as old as this pe- 
 riod, and consequently not the pro- 
 duction of Xenophon. 
 
 I have already remarked in book i. 
 ch. 8, that I will not answer for its 
 being the work of Xenophon; but 
 the proofs to the contrary I con- 
 sider as insufficient. That the domi- 
 nion of the sea did not belong to 
 Athens after the 9Srd Olympiad (b.c. 
 405) is not entirely true. The battle 
 of Cnidos brought subject allies again 
 under the power of Athens (book iii. 
 ch.l7), and why should not the Athe- 
 nians have again introduced their com- 
 pulsory jurisdiction ? Isocrates (Areo- 
 pag. 1) speaks in the most unambiguous 
 manner of the naval dominion of the 
 Athenians and of their numerous allies 
 after the victories of Tiraotheus : elpf)- 
 vrjv 8e Kal to. nepi tt]v x.'^pav dyovarjs, 
 Kal tS)U Kara OdXaao-av dpxovarjs, en 
 de avixp.a.)(Ovs ixovarfs, ttoWovs fxev 
 Tovs €ToifJiovs T]p.1v, fjv Ti dcTj, jHorjdr]- 
 (TovTus, TToXv di TrXciovs Toiis ras crvv- 
 rd^eis vnoTekovvras Koi to npoa-raT- 
 TOfxcvov noLovvras. It is certainly 
 remarkable that the tributes shoidd be 
 called <j)6poL; the name avvra^is was 
 not however introduced till Olymp. 
 100, 4 (B.C. 377): Xenophon may 
 either have written this treatise a short 
 time before, or, as appears to me more 
 probable, the ancient and customary 
 expression was retained in use later. 
 Comp. book iii. ch. 17- 
 
 That the tributes were valued every 
 four years is also an account to which 
 it is difficult to assign its proper place, 
 particularly in reference to earlier 
 times. According to book iii. ch. 11 
 
 and 15, the tributes were not altered 
 until the «9th Olympiad (b.c. 424), 
 and about Olymp. 91, 2 (b.c. 415) they 
 were entirely abohshed, and changed 
 into a custom duty, in which state 
 they remained until the dissolution of 
 the whole connexion by the battle of 
 yEgospotamos. Here then it might 
 be preferable to understand the times 
 after the battle of Cnidos, or after the 
 100th Olympiad (b.c. 377). When the 
 author speaks of the Athenians giving 
 up their own country, we are indeed 
 forcibly reminded of the first period of 
 the Peloponnesian war; but is it not 
 possible that ideas of this kind may 
 have been principles which were de- 
 rived from the earlier history of 
 Athens? 
 
 But the most singular passage of 
 all is the assertion of the writer, that it 
 was not allowed to ridicule the people 
 of Athens in comedies, but only indi- 
 viduals. In the Knights of Aristo- 
 phanes, which was acted in Olymp. 
 88, 4 (b.c. 424), and in the Wasps, 
 which was not brought forward till 
 later, the people, as Schneider remarks, 
 is ridiculed; but for this reason to 
 attribute to this writing a greater 
 antiquity than Olymp. 88, 4, would 
 be a bold assumption, nor would it 
 indeed be of much service. Aristo- 
 phanes had previously ridiculed the 
 state in the Babylonians (see Acharn. 
 502, and the schohast), and likewise 
 in the Acharneans, though qualified 
 with an apology which was produced 
 by particular circumstances, that he 
 only speaks against individuals, and 
 not against the state (vs. 514, 515). 
 The freedom of comedy was indeed 
 for a short time abridged, particularly 
 by a decree passed in Olymp. 85, J 
 (B.C. 440), which was however abro-
 
 322 
 
 THE HARBOUR DUTIES. 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 in assuming that this hundredth was an import duty, which was 
 levied at a particular period in place of the fiftieth ; for we find 
 the fiftieth mentioned both in the earUer time of Andocides 
 (whose lease of the custom duties, as well as that of Agyrrhius, 
 falls in the first years after the anarchy), and also in the time 
 Demosthenes ; and an alteration in this tax cannot be assumed 
 without any proof. May we not suppose that another harbour 
 duty was imposed in addition to the tax upon persons just men- 
 tioned, amounting to one per cent, on the cargo ? The more 
 
 gated in Olymp. 85, 4 (b.c. 437). 
 (Schol. Aristoph. Acharn. 67.) Ac- 
 cording to the scholiast to Ai'istoph. 
 Nub. 31, it was expressly prohibited to 
 ridicule the archon in comedy: and 
 according to the scholiast on Acharn, 
 1149, Antimachus, at the time when 
 he was choregus, had proposed a de- 
 cree that no one should be ridiculed by 
 name. All these accounts appear to 
 refer to the law passed in the archon- 
 ship of Morychides, and prove no more 
 than that it was forbidden to attack 
 anybody by name ; a prohibition which 
 was not long in force. On the other 
 hand, to ridicule the people, although 
 Cleon threw it out as a reproach 
 against Aristophanes (Acharn. 501), 
 and it would naturally produce hatred 
 against the poet, appears to have been 
 always allowed until after the time of 
 the anarchy. By this overthrow of 
 the democracy the Athenian demus 
 was rendered suspicious and mistrust- 
 ful ; and the parabasis, in which public 
 matters were discussed, was omitted. 
 Of this however want of space pre- 
 vents me from treating; with regard 
 to the passage in question, it agi-ees as 
 well with the time which succeeded 
 the anarchy as with the beginning of 
 the Peloponnesian war. 
 
 Lastly, Schneider was justly sur- 
 prised at the following passage : oXt'yot 
 de Tiues Ta)V Trfvr]T(i>v Koi tcov fir;ju.orcoj/ 
 KO}^to8ovvTai, KCil ovS' ovTOi, iav fxrj 8ici 
 iroXvnpayfiocrvvriv koi dia to Cr]Tf7v 
 
 irKeov €\eiv tov br]fiov: which, it ap- 
 pears, could not have been said after 
 the ill treatment of Socrates by the 
 comic poets, and least of all by Xeno- 
 phon. If however Xenophon wrote 
 this essay perhaps forty years after the 
 representation of the Clouds, when all 
 the circumstances of the times had 
 been changed, was it necessary that he 
 should refer to Socrates in an ironical 
 accoxmt of the principles of the Athe- 
 nians ? And could the best friend of 
 Socrates, or even Socrates himself, 
 deny that he wished to raise himself 
 above the people, he who came for- 
 ward as the ameliorator of the people, 
 and was not only a declared enemy of 
 the demus, but entertained purely aris- 
 tocratical principles? I may also make 
 a remark upon the observation occur- 
 ring in 1, 10, that slaves at Athens were 
 not allowed to be beaten, for which 
 regulation a false reason is ironically 
 assigned. The true reason appears 
 to have been forgotten at the time 
 when the author wrote, namely, the 
 war. (Aristoph. Nub. 7.) When the 
 Clouds were acted, the circumstance 
 was evidently new, and the reason well 
 known. Consequently, this circum- 
 stance likewise seems to prove that 
 tliis writing had a later origin than the 
 Clouds of Aristophanes at the earliest. 
 I do not indeed consider the question 
 to be set at rest by these arguments ; 
 but the space does not allow of a 
 more detailed investigation.
 
 CH. v.] THE MARKET TOLLS. 323 
 
 strangers came to Athens^ the greater was the intercourse ; if a 
 larger number of vessels arrived, even without bringing any 
 commodities for importation, the harbour duty was increased by 
 the influx of foreigners. At the same time I only throw out 
 this notion as a conjecture, for we know nothing certain of the 
 hundredth. Aristophanes speaks of many taxes of a hundredth 
 collected by Athens^% which, according to the scholiast, the 
 states paid for the duties {reXTj) ; an explanation more obscure 
 than the thing explained. It is however possible that this small 
 tax was le^^ed in Attica upon several occasions, a question which 
 we shall presently reconsider. 
 
 Duties levied in markets are mentioned in Attica, as well as 
 in other countries of Greece^*, and were considered as a tax of 
 importance, so that they could not have been mere fees paid 
 for permission to erect booths. It is more probable that they 
 were an excise duty upon all things sold in the market ; but in 
 what manner the rate was estimated we are wholly unable to 
 state. The grammarians^^ mention a tax upon sales (eiroiVLov, 
 iircovta)^ but they did not themselves know accurately what was 
 its nature. Harpocration conjectures that it was the tax of a 
 fifth (77 irefiiTTn), a duty of which he appears to have obtained 
 some knowledge from other sources ; other grammarians copy 
 this account from him ; but, if we consider the moderate rate 
 of the other duties, it is not credible that so high a tax should 
 have been imposed upon all sales, which would have fallen 
 chiefly upon the home consumption. In another account, which 
 in all probability is equally founded on mere conjecture, certain 
 duties of a hundredth are cited as instances of this tax. At 
 Byzantium we meet with a tax of ten per cent, upon sales, but 
 only imposed for the moment, and not intended for any long 
 
 83 Vesp. 656. fVt rfi oivrj TrpoaKara^aWofieva, aairep 
 
 ** Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, Aristoph. 1 eKaToarai rives. The sale of duties 
 Acharn. 904, ed. Invern. Demosth. cannot here be meant, although the 
 Olynth. i. p. 15, 20. I grammarian classes the KrjpvKeia, the 
 
 "* Pollux vii. 15. Harpocration, pay of the criers at the sale of the 
 Suid. Etymol. Phavorinus. The fol- j duties, together with the enavia, the 
 lowing less valuable statement occurs ! former being a fee which was perliaps 
 in Lex. Seg. p. 255, 'Enavia fiev to. exacted in all sales by auction. 
 
 Y 2
 
 324 
 
 THE MARKET TOLLS. 
 
 [bk. iir. 
 
 continuance"": other examples of large excise duties of this kind 
 I omit to enumerate. 
 
 Whether this tax was collected at the gates or in the market 
 I do not find anywhere stated^; toll-gatherers were, however, 
 appointed for the collection of it. A story preserved in Zeno- 
 bius and other compilers of proverbs^^, of a countryman named 
 Leucon, leads to this conclusion. The story is, that this Leu- 
 con used to place leathern bottles of honey in a panier, upon 
 the top of which he laid some barley, and brought it to Athens 
 on an ass, which he represented to be loaded with nothing but 
 l)arley. One day the ass fell down, and the toll-gatherers, 
 coming to his assistance, discovered the honey, and seized it as 
 contraband. This story indeed is in all probability a fiction, 
 and did not actually happen to any Leucon. Leucon was an 
 Athenian comic poet, perhaps the son of Hagnon^^ the con- 
 temporary of Aristophanes and Pherecrates, and he had repre- 
 sented the misfortune of the peasant upon the stage, in a play 
 called the Ass which carried the leathern bottles. This does not 
 however invalidate the argument; for even if it was not founded 
 upon any real fact, it must, in order to be made the subject of a 
 play, have been at least a possible occurrence according to the 
 existing usages at Athens. 
 
 "^ Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. 2, 3, in the 
 words roTs S' wvovfievois ri era^av 
 X^P^s TTJs Ti^rjs didovai einbeKaTov, 
 
 " The author mentions in the Ad- 
 denda, that having left it undecided 
 where the duty was paid upon goods 
 that were brought for sale into the 
 city, he afterwards considered that it 
 Avas probably taken at the gates, and 
 that the passage duty, or dcanvXiov, re- 
 fers to this. " The only account of it 
 is found in Ilesychius. ALunvXiov (as 
 has been rightly corrected) reXos tl 
 Trap"" ^Adrjuaiois ovrcos e/caXetro, where 
 consult tlie notes of the commentators : 
 the word is used in a somewhat differ- 
 ent meaning in Pseud- Aristot. fficon. 
 ii 2, 14, from whence it might be con- 
 cJiul'wl tlitit tlie money was ouly paid 
 
 for passing through the gate; but 
 at Athens the word might have had 
 any other signification, and that the 
 diaTTvXtov was some kind of admit- 
 tance money, appears to me hardly 
 conceivable." 
 
 ^'' Zenob. i. 74; Mich. Apost. ii. 08. 
 Comp. Diogenianus and Suidas vol. i. 
 p. 98. 
 
 ^^ Suid. in v. AevKav, and particu- 
 larly Toup Emend, in Suid. vol- ii. p. 
 252, ed. Leip. against the commenta- 
 tors. Respecting the time at which 
 he lived, see Athen. viii. p. 343 C. 
 llis ^pdropes is quoted by Athenseus, 
 Hesychius, Photius, and Suidas; the 
 latter mentions two other pieceSj^Ovos 
 and ' A(rKo<fi6pos ; both however are 
 one, viz. "Ovos aaKn<f)6poi.
 
 ch. vi.j tithesj their different sorts. 325 
 
 Chapter VL 
 
 The Duty of a Twentieth part. Tithes ; their different sorts. 
 
 In addition to these regular duties, the Athenians began, about 
 Olymp. 91, 2 (b.c. 415), to substitute in the room of the tri- 
 butes, which up to this period had been periodically paid by 
 the allies, a duty of a twentieth {eUoarr)) upon all commodities 
 exported or imported by sea in the states of the subject allies ; 
 hoping to raise a greater revenue by that means than by the 
 direct taxation of these states^^• and it cannot be doubted that 
 this tax, as Aristophanes mentions no less than 1000 tributary 
 cities, must have produced a very considerable revenue. It 
 was, according to the usual practice, let out in farm ; the collec- 
 tors had the name of eicostologi [elKoaroXo^oiY^ , From a 
 reference made by Aristophanes in the comedy of the Frogs 
 (Olymp. 93, 3, B.C. 405), to an unfortunate eicostologus, who 
 sent some contraband commodities from ^gina to Epidaurus, 
 it may be inferred that this duty had not been abolished, but 
 lasted until the end of the Peloponnesian war. 
 
 But the tenth {SeKaTij) raised by the Athenians at Byzan- 
 tium was a mere extortion. It was first imposed in Olymp. 92, f 
 (b.c. 409), when Alcibiades, Thrasyllus, and the other Athe- 
 nian generals who came from Cyzicus, fortified Chrysopolis in 
 the territory of Chalcedon : a station for the reception of those 
 duties [heKarevrripLov) was built, and thirty ships were sent out 
 under two generals, in order to tithe the commodities on board 
 all ships which came out of the Pontus, as Xenophon relates^'. 
 Polybius mentions the ships going to the Pontus ; both accounts 
 are doubtless correct, and the tenth was levied upon the cargoes 
 of vessels both coming in and going out of this sea. That this 
 
 "^ Thucyd. \ii. 28. To this twen- 
 tieth and to the Byzantine transit 
 duties, Avhich will be presently men- 
 tioned, the following passage refers in 
 Lex. Scg. p. 185, 21, Aexar/; Kcti elKOdTi]' 
 
 iXdfx^avov. 
 
 ^<> Pollux ix. 30; Aristoph. Ran. 
 366. 
 
 »' Hellen. i. 1, 14, with which Dio- 
 dorus xii. 64 agrees.
 
 326 tithes; their different sorts. [bk. hi. 
 
 tax produced a large revenue may be readily conceived, for the 
 rate of duty was high, and this channel was very much fre- 
 quented. " Byzantium," says Polybius'% " is most favourably 
 situated upon the sea of any known place ;'^ against the will of 
 its inhabitants, it was not possible either to go out of or to come 
 in to the Pontus, on account of the rapid current in the straits; 
 for that reason it was far more fortunately situated than Chalce- 
 don, the City of the Blind, w^hich at first sight appears to have 
 possessed an equally advantageous position: a large supply of 
 leather, the best and the greatest number of slaves, came from 
 the Pontus; also honey, wax, and salt meat; oil, and every kind 
 of wine, were carried from Greece into the Black Sea; corn it 
 sometimes exported and sometimes imported. The only good 
 passage however, as the same historian remarks, was by Bus and 
 Chrysopolis, for which reason the Athenians, upon the advice of 
 Alcibiades, had chosen this latter city as the station for collect- 
 ing the duties. Of this tax they were deprived by the defeat 
 at ^gospotamos. Thrasybulus however reestablished it about 
 the 97th Olympiad (b.c. 390), and let it out in farm*^; at that 
 time the Athenians derived great resources from it for the carry- 
 ing on of war. The peace of Antalcidas (Olymp. 98, 2, b.c. 
 .387)^ probably produced its second abolition; and a long 
 time afterwards (Olymp. 139, b.c. 224), the Byzantians, to 
 assist a pecuniary difficulty, introduced the same transit duties 
 {Btaywyiov), which were the cause of the war waged against 
 them by the Rhodians®\ 
 
 AVherever houses or stations for the collection of tenths 
 (heKarevrripta, heKarrfKo'yLa) are mentioned", tolls collected at 
 sea are always to be understood, which required particular esta- 
 blishments of this description. Therefore Pollux mentions the 
 erection of them as an event which only happened on particular 
 occasions. But w^hen farmers of tenths, and collectors of 
 
 «^ Polyb. iv. 38, and afterwards 43, 
 44. 
 
 " Xeuopli. Ilelleu. iv. 8, 27, 31 ; 
 Demosth. c. Leptin. § 48, and there 
 Ulpian's and Wolf's notes. 44, 46; iii 
 
 ''' Polybius in the following chap- ^' Tollux viii. 13 
 
 ters. Comp. Heyne de Byzaut. p. 15 
 sqq. To compel a person to sail to the 
 place where the duties were collected 
 was called Trapayatyid^eLv, Polyb. iv.
 
 CH. VI.] tithes; their different sorts. 327 
 
 tenths (Se/caTMvaL, BeKarrjXoyot, BeKarevral) are mentioned^% 
 duties of different descriptions may be understood. In the 
 first place there were the tenths of the produce of the soil; we 
 know^ for example, that this tax was collected in the govern- 
 ments of the satraps, as a distinct branch of revenue; it was 
 also universally extended in the tyrannies of Asia, and probably 
 w^as the most ancient tax paid to the kings. Thus too the 
 Romans collected tenths from conquered countries; and this 
 same duty was also very common in Greece, but only as a tax 
 upon property which was not freehold, the tenths being paid for 
 the use. Consistently with this the tyrant demanded the 
 tenths from all his subjects, as lord and master of the whole 
 country, which he only permitted to be occupied by his subjects 
 upon the payment of these taxes. Of this kind are the Sicilian 
 tenths, which were received by the kings before that country 
 fell into the hands of the Romans ; and many cases of the same 
 duty occur in Greece Proper, as, for example, the tithes of the 
 corn at Cranon in Thessaly^^; thus Pisistratus, as tyrant or 
 usurping proprietor of the country, subjected all the lands of 
 the Athenian citizens to a tithe, and incurred the hatred of his 
 people by this despotic measure; although as a sophist sup- 
 poses him to say in a spurious epistle, he might excuse himself 
 by alleging, that the tithes were not paid for himself the tyrant, 
 but for defraying the expenses of the sacrifices, with the other 
 branches of the administration, and the costs of war®^. The 
 Pisistratidae did not abolish this tax, but they lowered it to a 
 twentieth^ ^ 
 
 ®° AeKarcovai are farmei-s of the I Kareveiv, reXKovetv, not to quote other 
 
 tenths, deKarrjXoyoi, collectors of the 
 tenths ; both of which callings were 
 often united in the same individual: 
 d(KaT€VTa\ appears to be applicable to 
 either. Cf. Harpocrat. in w. 8eKa- 
 Tevras and deKaTrjXoyos, Pollux ix. 28 ; 
 Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 676, 26. 
 Also Hesychius in v. deKarqXoyoi, Ety- 
 mol. in V. SeKaTevrrjpiov, where how- 
 ever the statements given are incor- 
 rect and confused. To collect the 
 tenth was called deKarcvdv. Aristo- 
 phanes ap. Poll. ix. 31, eXXiiieviCeis ^ 
 8(KaT€V€is ; and thence Hesychius 6e- 
 
 grammanans. 
 
 ^7 Poly^en. ii. 34. 
 
 ^^ Concerning these tenths see Meur- 
 sius Pisistrat. 6, 7,9. The spurious 
 epistle is given by Diogenes Laertius 
 in the Life of Solon. 
 
 ^® 'EIkocttt] tcov yiyvofievcou, Thucyd. 
 vi. 64. In the free constitution of 
 Athens nothing of this kind occurs. 
 That the Roman tenths were copied 
 from those of Attica is the singular 
 notion of Burmann de Vect. P. R. ii, 
 and v.
 
 328 tithes; their different sorts. [bk. hi. 
 
 In the same manner that, with reference to a tyrant, all 
 lands were subject to a tithe, so in a republic many estates were 
 subject to this tax, as not being the freehold property of the 
 possessor, but only held by him as occupier. Thus the state of 
 Athens owned the tithes of public demesnes, and let them in 
 farm; the temples also frequently enjoyed property of this kind, 
 of which many examples are extant: thus, for instance, the 
 Delian Apollo received a large amount of tithes from the 
 Cyclades'""; and in the island of Ithaca, the temple of Diana 
 received the tithes from an estate, the possessors of which were 
 bound to keep her temple in repair^"'; and Xenophon had for- 
 merly devised the very same regulation at Scillus. Obligations 
 of this nature arose in great measure from the piety of indi- 
 viduals, who dedicated their property to the gods, and thus gave 
 up the ownership or dominion, retaining at the same time the 
 use of it for themselves in consideration of a fixed payment; 
 the temples may also on certain occasions have received the 
 right of tithes by conquest. Thus the Greeks promised that 
 after the fortunate termination of the Persian war, all states 
 who had afforded any protection to the enemy, should pay a 
 tithe to the Delphian Apollo, that is to say, that they would 
 make their lands subject to a tribute'"*. At Athens, moreover, 
 Minerva of the Parthenon received the tithe of the plunder, and 
 of captures'"^, and also of certain fines ^''■'; while others were paid 
 to the temples without any deduction, together with the tithe 
 either of all or of a large proportion of confiscated property '"\ 
 The tithes of Minerva are mentioned in connexion with the 
 
 ^'^ Spanheim ad Callim. Hymn. 
 Del. 278 ; Coi-sini Gr. Diss. \i. p. cxvi. 
 
 '•" Coi-p. Inscript. No. 1926. See 
 Paciaudi Mon. Pelop. vol. i. p. 142, 
 
 ^0^ Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 741, 3; 
 Diod. xi. 62; Lysias c. Polystrat. p. 
 686; Ilarpocrat. in v. deKareveiv, 
 Comp. Paciaudi ut sup. p. 172 sqq.; 
 
 and his diflPuse notes, where tlie ge- ■ Lakemacher Ant. Grrec. Sacra, p. 400. 
 nuinoness of tlie inscription is proved. , '*^^ Cf. e. g. Demosth. c. IMacart. p. 
 Xenophon sot up the very same in- 1074, 24. 
 
 scription at Scilhis (Cyr. Exped. v. 3, ' ^"^ Decree in the Lives of the Ten 
 3,) and this inscription of Ithaca is a I Orators, p. 226 ; Andocid. de Myst. p. 
 somewhat modem imitation of it, but . 48. Xenoph. Hellen. i. 7, 10. Com- 
 unquestionably not a forgery. | pare book iii. eh. 14. Photius men- 
 
 '"Mlerod. vii. 132 ; Diod. xi. 3 ;' tions a tenth received by tlie gods in v. 
 Polyb. ix. 33, concerning Thebes. Cf. i aBeKarevrnvSy without however speci- 
 Xenoph. llellcn. vi. 3, U. I fying which.
 
 CH. VII.] 
 
 TAXES UPON ALIENS. 
 
 329 
 
 fiftieths of other gods^ and of the heroes of the tribes [kirciivv- 
 fioi)^^^; the latter were probably similar per ceiitages, and must 
 not be confomided with the custom duty of the fiftieth. 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 Taxes upon Aliens, Taxes upon Slaves, and other Personal Taxes, 
 
 Among the direct and personal taxes^ the protection money of 
 the resident aliens {fjuerolKiov) is most generally known, an 
 institution by no means peculiar to the Athenian state, but 
 which was introduced in many'"^, and perhaps in all countries. 
 At Athens every resident alien paid twelve drachmas a year, as 
 we learn from the testimony of Eubulus and Iseeus"^^; according 
 to the latter, the women paid 6 drachmas, if they had no son 
 of sufficient age to pay for himself. If however the son paid the 
 protection money, the mother was exempt; consequently no 
 woman paid it, excej)t those whose families did not contain any 
 adiilt male; and as the son exempted the mother, there can be 
 no doubt that the husband exempted his wife. For that the 
 wives of the resident aliens had to make a separate payment is 
 improbable for this reason, that otherwise a widow, even if her 
 son paid this tax, would also have been required to pay for her- 
 self; whereas it is stated in the most general terms, that if the 
 son paid, the mother did not, nor consequently the widow. 
 The protection money was also farmed out; since farmers of 
 duties (reXwva^) are mentioned in connexion with it; for example 
 in the Life of Lycurgus, who threatened a farmer of duties with 
 imprisonment, for arresting Xenocrates for not having paid his 
 protection money^''^ and also in the grammarians. It is main- 
 
 106 Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 738, 5, 
 and Ulpian's note. 
 
 i"? Besides the two passages of Ly- 
 sias and Lycurgus which Wesseling 
 quotes ad Petit, ii. 5, 1, see Demosth. 
 c. Aristocrat, p. 691, 3, and c. Aphob. 
 ^l^evSo/x. p. 845, 19. 
 
 '°^ Harpocration in v. fxeToUiov, cf. 
 Lex. Seg. p. 280, Hesychius in v. fxe- 
 
 TotKOL, Photius, who transcribes Har- 
 pocration, in V. jieToiKoi and fxeroiKaiu 
 XeiTovpyioL, Polhix iii. 55, Nicephor. 
 ad Syues. de Insomn. p. 402. The 
 other statement of 10 drachmas in 
 Hesychius v. fieToUiov and Ammonins 
 V. la-oreXrjs only rests upon an error of 
 the copyist. 
 
 ^09 Yit. Dec. Orat. vol. iv. p. 253,
 
 330 
 
 I'AXES UPON ALIENS. [bK. III. 
 
 tallied by some writers, that tlie payment of the protection 
 money was made by the patron (Trpoo-rarTy?) ''% which agrees very 
 well with his character of surety for the resident aliens, but is 
 directly opposed to the testimonies of the ancients. For the 
 state looked for security to the body of the resident ahen him- 
 self, and if he was convicted before the poletae of non-payment 
 of the duty, he was immediately sold''\ It is also to be obsers^ed 
 that Harpocration, who is followed by Photius, proves from the 
 comic poets in particular, that the freed men also paid this pro- 
 tection money; Menander, however, he proceeds to state, says 
 in two plays, " that besides the ] 2 drachmas, the latter also paid 
 3 oboli, perhaps to the farmer of the duties.'^ According to the 
 context the ^^latter" can only be the freed men, as Petit rightly 
 understood it''^; and, as is so frequently the case, Pollux and 
 Hesychius generalize this account of the payment of the trio- 
 bolon, and extend it to all resident aliens. But they go still 
 farther than this, for the latter informs us that it was paid to 
 the farmer of the duties, the former, that the clerk received it. 
 The general accuracy and information of Harpocration prove 
 that no grammarian could know it for certain, and to what pur- 
 pose should it have been paid to a clerk, or even to a farmer 
 of the duties, if the tax was farmed out ? This triobolon paid by 
 the freed men must therefore have had a different character, to 
 which point I will presently return. On the other hand many 
 resident aliens, as is implied in the story of Xenocrates, enjoyed 
 an immunity from the protection money [areXeca fMerocKvov) 
 
 cd. Tubing. ; also Plutarch in the Life tliere is an instance of the sale of an 
 of Q. Flaminimis, and Photius in the ; unmarried woman. The place where 
 Life of Lycurgus. Concerning Xeno- j this sale took place was called the tto). 
 crates see also Plutarch's Phocion 29, ! XrjTTjpiov tov fieroiKLov. The sale was 
 and Ste. Croix in his ^Memoir on the j carried on under the direction of the 
 fxeroiKoi in the Mem. de I'Academie ] poletse, Pollux viii. 99, comp. above 
 des Inscriptions, torn. xLvii. p. 184 sq. I book ii. ch. 3. The protection money 
 
 "•^ Petit ubi sup. and Lex. Seg. p. j was naturally sold by auction in the 
 298. j same place. In the Lives of the Ten 
 
 '" Harpocration, from the Oration Orators fieroiKiov is incorrectly used 
 against Aristogiton i. p. 787, 27, which j instead of ncokijTrjpLov tov fifToiKiov. 
 if not written by Demosthenes him- "=^ Leg. Att. ii. 6, 7. 
 
 self, is of considerable auti(iuity, where
 
 CII. VII.j TAXES UPON SLAVES. 331 
 
 without being isoteles, at Athens as well as in other countries"^ 
 Many were even exempted from custom duties' '*, and other 
 payments, as will be shown below; yet these preferences appear 
 to have been very rare; for, according to Demosthenes "% 
 scarcely five persons were exempted from the regular liturgies, 
 and what Diodorus''^ supposes Themistocles to say with regard 
 to the immunity of the resident aliens and the artificers, must 
 have arisen from some misunderstanding, which perhaps origi- 
 nated in the circumstance that Themistocles had encouraged this 
 class in some other manner. If then we take the sum of the 
 resident aliens in the time of Demetrius Phalereus, which was 
 10,000, as an average amount, and reckon about 1000 women 
 who paid this tax, the protection money would have amounted to 
 about 21 talents: the freed men are included in this estimate, 
 although in Xenophon^s Treatise upon the State of Athens'", 
 this class of persons is distinguished from the resident ahens. 
 
 Xenophon says"% that '^ whoever remembers how much the 
 slave duty produced before the Decelean war, will allow that it 
 is possible to maintain a large number of slaves in the country.^"* 
 At that period great numbers eloped; Thucydides reckons more 
 than 20,000; the maritime wars destroyed a very large number, 
 and as it was easy for them to escape from Attica, the Athenians 
 probably reduced their establishments, or exported their slaves 
 to foreign markets. In short, Athens had more slaves before 
 than after the Decelean war, and this duty was consequently 
 more productive. But by means of what? was it merely by the 
 duty of a fiftieth upon their importation? In that case the 
 expression slave duty could scarcely have been used. It is more 
 probable that a tax upon the slaves themselves existed: and this 
 would in that case be the only direct and regular taxation of a 
 part of the property of the citizens, excepting the liturgies; 
 although this duty, in so far as slaves cannot be considered as 
 mere property, but as servants also, may be viewed in the light 
 
 "^ Corp. Inscript. No. 87, ad fin. "'' i. 10; see b. i. ch. 7. 
 Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 691, 3. I ns y)q Vectig. 4, ocrov to reXos ev- 
 
 "■* Book i. ch. 15. . picKe t5>v avbpanoboiv npo tcou iv 
 
 "* C. Leptin. § 16, 17. AcKeX^ia. 
 
 116 
 
 XI. 43.
 
 3.32 
 
 TAXES UPON SLAVES. [bK. III. 
 
 of a tax upon servants. Now the supposition that a slave tax 
 of this nature was in existence, appears to be confirmed by the 
 triobolon which was paid by the freed men. The rate of taxa- 
 tion for slaves could not indeed have been high, if it was not to 
 press too heavily upon the property of persons who employed a 
 large number, and particularly of the mine proprietors; but 
 3 oboli a year for each slave was a tax that would easily have 
 been borne; and it is probable that the possessors paid this 
 sum for every slave; of which the triobolon paid by each freed 
 man in addition to the protection money, was probably the 
 result: the latter he paid by virtue of his new station; but the 
 state would not consent to renounce what it had formerly 
 received from him. If this supposition is well founded, and we 
 reckon 400,000 slaves in Attica, the tax produced to the farmer 
 of the duties 200,000 drachmas, or about 33 talents a year. 
 
 From this example it may be perceived how limited is our 
 knowledge even of the Athenian antiquities. Obliterate the few 
 and indistinct traces of this tax upon slaves, and there is 
 nowhere an indication of its existence. How many similar 
 duties and revenues may Athens have possessed, of which we 
 know nothing? In the state of Byzantium, fortune-tellers (who, 
 as may be seen from Isocrates and Lucian, carried on a profit- 
 able trade), quacks, jugglers, and other itinerant impostors paid 
 the third part of their profits for permission to follow their 
 callings^ ^^, and traders of this description were also taxed in 
 other countries in ancient times^^"; it is fair to suppose that 
 Athens likewise levied a similar tax. 
 
 Even retail-dealing in the market was not permitted either 
 to the resident aliens or to foreigners, without the payment of 
 a tax, which was known by the name of foreigners^ money 
 (^eviKci reXetv); hence Demosthenes says of a woman who sold 
 ribbands, that if they wished to prove that she was a foreigner 
 and not a citizen, they must search the duties collected in the 
 market'*'; and perhaps the resident aliens j^aid a tax even for 
 the exercise of other trades. 
 
 'i» Pseud-Aristot. CEcon. 2, 3. | ^-^i Dcmosth. c. Eubulid. p. 130«, I), 
 
 '-*' CiLsaub. ad Suetou. Ctilig. 40. | p. 130i), 5.
 
 CII. VII.] PERSO.NAL TAXES. 333 
 
 The most shameful of all taxes of this class is the tax upon 
 prostitutes {iropviKov reXos), which was likewise introduced 
 in Rome by Caligula, and not only continued during the reigns 
 of the Christian emperors '^% but to the disgrace of mankind 
 still exists in Christian states. At Athens it was annually let 
 out by the senate; the farmers knew accurately the names of 
 all who followed this calling' ^^, men as well as women; for even 
 the former, as was the case under Caligula, paid the tax. Ac- 
 cording to a passage of Suidas and Zonaras'^*, the agoranomi 
 fixed the price which each prostitute was to take: it appears 
 therefore that the tax was different according to their different 
 profits' ^^^ as was the case in the ordinance of Caligula''^^. If 
 persons of the rank of citizens demeaned themselves in this 
 manner (which the laws endeavoured to hinder, by excluding 
 them from sacrifices and public offices, and by other wise regu- 
 lations), they were also subject to the tax, although the citizens 
 did not pay anything for following honourable callings. 
 
 Lastly, the state had some revenues of a smaller kind, which 
 reverted from the expenses, and although they bear no resem- 
 blance to those which have been here enumerated, yet they 
 cannot be mentioned with greater propriety in any other place. 
 Among these is the hide money [hepfiaTLKov), which was 
 derived from great sacrifices and feasts "'^ 
 
 ''^^ Burmann de Vectig. Pop. Rom. 
 xii. Hegewisch liber die Rcimischen 
 Finanzen, p. 213, p. 308, sqq. 
 
 ^*^ ^scliin. c. Timarch. p. 134, 135. 
 These fanners are also reXaivai, oi 
 €K\€yov(Ti TO reXos. The expression 
 TTopvoTcXccvaL in the comic poet Philo- 
 
 names applied to fanners of duties in 
 general. [See INIeineke, Fr. Com. Gr. 
 vol. ii. p. 421. Transl.] 
 
 ^'^* In V. Stdypafifia. 
 
 ^^^ Comp. above book i. ch. 21. 
 
 ^2° Sue'tou. Calig. 40. Ex capturis 
 prostitutamm, quantum quajque nno 
 
 nides (Pollux vii. 202, and the com- ; concubitu mereret. 
 
 mentators) refers to the tax in ques- j '"'^ See book iii. ch. 19, and Corp. 
 
 tion, although PoUux (ix. 29) cites i Inscript. No. 157. 
 
 this word among the vituperative I
 
 334 GEXKKAL UK MARKS UPON [bK. II 
 
 Chapter VIII. 
 
 General Remarks upon the foregoing Taxes, particularly upon 
 the mode of levying and paying them. 
 
 The government of Athens cannot be accused of having levied 
 any regular duties, which were so high as to be oppressive; 
 other states appear to have imposed far heavier taxes, as, for 
 example, Cersobleptes in the Chersonese laid a duty of a tenth 
 upon all commodities '^% and Leucon, king in the Bosporus, 
 imposed a tax of a thirtieth upon exported corn''^^ In Baljylon 
 all goods entering the town were subject to a tithe; this prac- 
 tice had, however, fallen into disuse long before the time of 
 Alexander'^*'. The Lampsacenians, on an occasion when many 
 triremes, and consequently a considerable sale of provisions, 
 were expected, laid an excise duty of half the usual price upon 
 all commodities^^^ It is, indeed, undeniable that the method 
 of collection by a farmer-general, to whom the duties were sold, 
 diminished the receipts of the state^^^ This custom, however, 
 was not peculiar to Athens: for the duties were farmed out in 
 all the countries of Greece, and also in the kingdoms of Mace- 
 donia and Rome. We have already seen from Andocides how 
 those persons who wished to take a lease were able to defraud 
 the public at the auction of the duties ; the farmers of the cus- 
 tom duties made a conspiracy against the state, bought off any 
 competitors who wished to overbid them, either by direct 
 bribery or by giving them a share in the letting, or even perse- 
 cuted those who deprived them of the lease, as was the case 
 with Andocides himself. The same fact is proved by another 
 case mentioned in Plutarch^". A resident alien, whose pro- 
 perty did not amount to more than 100 staters, conceived a 
 passion for Alcibiades, and brought him his whole stock of 
 
 ^-^ Demosth.c. Aristocrat, p. 679,24. f ^'-'^ The expressions used are t^Xt) 
 '-^ Demosth. c. Leptin. ^^20. cKdibovai, -mnpacTK^iv, nTrofiiaBovv, 
 
 '^'" rseud-Aristot. CEcon. 2, 34. PoUux, ix. 34. 
 
 '^" Ibid. 2, 7. I '^^ Alcib. 5.
 
 CH. 
 
 VIII.] 
 
 THE FOREGOING TAXES. 
 
 335 
 
 ready money, in order to move him to a return of aiFection. 
 Alcibiades, pleased with the love and devotion of this person, 
 invited him to be his guest; he then returned him the money, 
 charging him at the same time to bid against the farmers of the 
 duties upon the following day, towards whom he had a particu- 
 lar cause of enmity. When the poor man excused himself on 
 the plea that the letting was an affair of many talents, Alcibia- 
 des threatened to flog him, in case he did not comply with his 
 wishes : the alien then obeyed him, and upon the following day, 
 at the sale of the duties in the market-place, he increased the 
 former bidding by a talent, and Alcibiades himself provided 
 him with security, to the vexation of the farmers of the custom 
 duties. The company of farmers, who were always accustomed 
 with the second letting to pay oflf the debts of the first, seeing 
 that there was no means of extricating themselves from the 
 difficulty, offered the man money to withdraw his bidding; 
 upon which Alcibiades did not allow him to take less than a 
 talent. 
 
 Three separate descriptions of persons were connected with the 
 management of every duty, viz., tho, f manners or lessees (jeXcovat, 
 TTptd/jLevoL, or oDvov/jbevoL to riXo^, rarely /jutcrOovfjLevoi, except in 
 the letting of landed property and not of duties), the sureties, 
 {eyyvoL^ iyyvTjTai), and the collector's {eK\oy6ls)^^\ The last 
 expression has two meanings: it sometimes signifies the public 
 officers, who in the name of the state exacted payment of the 
 public money (hence the persons who collected the tribute, 
 which w^as never farmed out, were called by this name'"); and 
 sometimes it is used to signify those who collected the duty 
 in the name of the farmer-general: which of these two meanings 
 is required in the particular passage, it belongs to the commen- 
 tator to decide. The sureties, as is proved by the examples 
 already quoted, were appointed at the taking of the lease; it is 
 probable that they frequently had a share in the profit of the 
 
 ^^* Law of Timocrates in Demosth. 
 c. Timocrat. p. 713, 3. The oath of 
 the senators in the same speech p. 745, 
 15. 
 
 ^^^ Harpocration, Suidas in v. inXo- 
 yelsy Lex. Seg. p. 245. 'EKXeyeiu to 
 
 TfXos is also 
 meanings. 
 
 nsed in two different
 
 336 GENERAL REMARKS UPON [bK. Ill, 
 
 contractors. More extensive lettings were taken by cotnpanies, 
 as may be seen from Andocides, Lycurgus^'% and Plutarch. 
 At the head of these associations was placed the chief farmer 
 (tt)0%ft)V77S', reXcovdpxv^)' Persons of noble descent, who were 
 proud of their station and dignity, never entered into business 
 of this description; but these farmers were generally respectable 
 citizens, and sometimes even statesmen; as, for instance, Agyr- 
 rhius the demagogue, and Andocides the merchant and orator. 
 Resident aliens were also entitled to take leases of custom 
 duties; but the grant of property subject to a rent, as for exam- 
 ple of mines, was limited to citizens and isoteles. The farmers 
 of custom duties (reXchvac) frequently occur in the character of 
 collectors, who appear to have been for the most part inferior 
 sharers in the letting, although hired servants or slaves of the 
 lessees were perhaps occasionally employed for this purpose. 
 According to the different duties which they farmed, these per- 
 sons had different names (eX/VtyLtevtcrral, SeKarTjXoyoi, elKoaro- 
 \6yoi, irevTTjKoaToXoyot, or less Attic, €LKocrTcovac, BeKarcovat, 
 Sic.y^'; and in like manner the places where the respective 
 duties were collected {reXcovca, irevTrjKoaToXoyLa^ BeKarijXoyca, 
 BeKaTevTTjpta, and others) ^^^ They kept their books '^% and 
 had power to seize commodities and persons'^": whether the 
 imposition of a seal upon the goods'", which was customary in 
 later times, had been introduced during the existence of the 
 republic, I do not undertake to decide: but all other vexations 
 of custom duties, such as a strict search and examination, even 
 opening of letters, are mentioned; the latter practice is indeed 
 only noticed in the Roman comedies, which is perhaps suffi- 
 cient testimony, as they for the most part represent the usages 
 of Athens'*'^ Fraud and smugghngwere however as difficult to 
 
 *^ C. Leocrat. p. 150, where an 
 action occurs, brought by one person 
 against another for defrauding him in 
 the company for farming the fiftieth. 
 Comp. also p. 179. 
 
 "7 See Pierson ad ]Stocrin p. 165. 
 
 *^» Polhix ix. 28, Lex. Seg. p. 230. 
 
 '^^ Comp. book iii. ch. 4, Pollux, ix. 
 31. 
 
 ^^^ Not to quote more than one 
 passage, see Demosth. c. Mid. p. 559, 
 18. 
 
 *^' See Barthelemy, Anacharsis, vol. 
 ii. p. 1G8. 
 
 ^*'^ Plant. Trinumm. iii. 3, 64 ; ^fe- 
 ncechm. i. 2, 5; Terent. Phorm. i. 2, 
 100, with the note of Douatus, and 
 Nonius in v. Telouarios.
 
 CH.VIII. ] 
 
 THE FOREGOING TAXES. 
 
 337 
 
 prevent in ancient times as at the present day; in Attica the 
 thieves' harbour {(jxopayv Xtfirjv) was much used for these pur- 
 poses'^^; and that the collectors of the duties were themselves 
 sometimes engaged in this unlawful traffic, is proved by the 
 instance of the Eicostologus in Aristophanes'**. Their dishonest 
 practices and oppressive conduct brought them into the worst re- 
 pute'**: indeed the displeasure and hatred which the collectors of 
 the Roman customs had excited were so great, that the state was 
 compelled to abolish the custom duties in Italy, to the manifest 
 loss of its revenue' *^ The peculiar legal relations between the 
 farmers of these duties and the state were defined by the laws 
 of the custom duties {vofjuoi Te\a)vt/cot)'*^ These also doubtless 
 contained particular enactments, with regard to offences con- 
 nected with the custom duties. That commodities which it was 
 attempted to smuggle in without the payment of a duty (areXco- 
 VTjTd, dva7r6ypa<j>ay*^ were forfeited by the Athenian as well as 
 by the Roman regulations, is evident from the example which 
 has been already quoted: as, however, at Athens it was allow- 
 able to institute a phasis against persons who had violated the 
 laws connected with the custom duties'*^ — in which form of 
 proceeding the assignment of the penalty was arbitrary — a 
 severer punishment might be brought on by aggravated circum- 
 stances. The father of Bion the Philosopher was sold, together 
 with his whole family, for an offence against the laws of the 
 custom duties, although this did not take place at Athens"". 
 The farmers of the custom duties were allowed by law an 
 exemption from military service'^', in order that they might 
 
 >« See Palmer Exercit. p. 639 ; 
 Lex Seg. p. 315. Concerning the way 
 in which the fanners of the duties 
 were cheated, see Jul. Afric. Cest. p. 
 304. 
 
 '** See the passage quoted above, 
 note 90. 
 
 "* Pollux ix. 29, 32. 
 
 '*^ Concerning the farmers of the 
 duties at Rome, compare with this 
 view Cicer. ad Quint. Frat. i. 1. To 
 how great a nicety the system of cus- 
 
 tom duties was brought by the Romans, 
 has been shown by Burmann de Vec- 
 tig. P. R. V. 
 
 '"7 Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 739, 
 29, p. 731, 1. 
 
 ^*^ The latter expression occurs in 
 Pollux ix. 31, the former inZenob. i.74. 
 
 i*» Pollux viii. 47. 
 
 ^^^ HapareXdnnjadixevos ti ttuvoikios 
 €7rpd6T}, Diog. Laert. iv. 46. 
 
 >5' Orat. c. Neser. p. 1353 ; Ulpian. 
 ad Mid. p. 685 A. 
 
 z
 
 338 
 
 GENERAL REMARKS UPON 
 
 [bK. Ill, 
 
 not be impeded in the collection of the duties; and although 
 Leocrates, as mentioned by Lycurgus, when a partner in the 
 lease of the fiftieth, does not appear to have availed himself of 
 this plea as an excuse for neglecting to serve in war'*% it is 
 possible that he had particular reasons for not taking that line 
 of defence. 
 
 The payment of the rents (Kara^oXr) reXovs, re\o9 Kara- 
 jSdWeLV, Karadelvac, BLoXvo-ac, airoBovvai, Kara^aXKeLV ras 
 Kara^oka^y^^ took place in the senate house, in the appointed 
 pr^^taneias'^^. If the farmer of the duties did not observe the 
 term of payment, it was ordered that he should at the latest 
 pay in the ninth pr}^taneia; if he failed to observe this term, 
 his debt was doubled; and if the double amount was not imme- 
 diately paid, his property was forfeited to the state. That this 
 regulation was in force before the time of the thirty tyrants, is 
 proved by the following words of Andocides'": "When the 
 fleet had been destroyed, and the siege commenced, you deli- 
 berated upon the expediency of concord among yourselves, and, 
 upon the proposal of Patrocleides, you decreed to restore to 
 their rights those who had been subjected to atimia. Now who 
 these persons that had been thus sentenced were, and what 
 were the circumstances connected with each case, I will men- 
 tion to you. They were then, in the first place, persons owing 
 money to the state, of whom some had filled official situations, 
 and had not passed their accounts; some were in debt to the 
 public, for obtaining wrongful possession of property {i^ovXac 
 in the widest sense), or in consequence of public suits (which 
 
 '•" Lycurg, c. Leocrat. p. 179. 
 
 '^ Pollux ix. 31, and frequently in 
 other writers. 
 
 ^** Orat. c. Neaer. ut sup. 
 
 '" De Myst. p. 35. Concerning the 
 abolition of the atimia see Xenoph. 
 Hellen, ii. 2, 6 ; and for the payment 
 of the double amount see Liban. Ar- 
 gum. ad Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 696, 
 2, and Demosthenes himself, p. 705, 1. 
 With regard to the e|oCXai see below, 
 chap. 12. From these fines the cVi- 
 
 ^oXa\ and the money paid for unsuc- 
 cessful ypa(f)aL are essentially different, 
 as every one will perceive from the 
 statements presently made. I may 
 observe that it has been inferred with 
 great probability (but not with abso- 
 lute certainty) from Andocides, p. 45 
 sqq. that the law relating to the public 
 debtors was repealed in the archonship 
 of Euclid ; it must however have been 
 again introduced, as it was indispens- 
 able.
 
 CH. VIII.] THE FOREGOING TAXES. 339 
 
 the accusers had lost), and for fines adjudged by a court of 
 justice {eTTLpoXal) ; others having taken leases from the public 
 had not paid the stipulated sum, or had been sureties to the 
 state: all these persons, I say, were permitted to pay on or 
 before the ninth prytaneia, and in case of non-payment they 
 were to be fined double, and their possessions sold for the 
 benefit of the state. This was one species of atimia.'^ This 
 passage only leaves one point doubtful, viz. whether the atimia 
 was not put into force until after the omission of the payment 
 in the ninth prytaneia, or whether it followed immediately upon 
 failure of payment at the appointed period. There can be no 
 question but that the latter was the case; the atimia was imme- 
 diately inflicted, if the first term of payment was neglected; 
 since otherwise no one would have paid until the ninth pryta- 
 neia: and the debtor could moreover be thrown into prison by 
 an augmentation of the punishment [irpoaTL^T^fjbaY'"^, 
 
 Both these facts may be seen from the speech of Demos- 
 thenes against Timocrates. The latter person had proposed a 
 law, which enacted that the public debtors should not be put in 
 prison before the ninth prytaneia; by which means, says the 
 orator^", he makes the augmentations of punishment invalid 
 (that is to say, he deprives the court of the right of inflicting 
 that penalty), and exempts the public debtors from atimia. 
 Here the atimia, together with the right of augmenting the 
 punishment, is evidently supposed to apply to the time pre- 
 ceding the ninth prytaneia: the penalty of excommunication or 
 atimia was moreover inseparably associated with the idea of a 
 public debtor, which every one became from the day on which 
 he should have made his payment. Lastly, the law of Timo- 
 crates shows that the person bound to pay was liable to 
 imprisonment immediately after the expiration of the first 
 term : he thus became a public debtor, and therefore subject to 
 atimia. Timocrates did not include the farmers of the duties 
 within the operation of his law, but intended that the ancient 
 
 ^^^ Concerning this see below, chap. 
 11. 
 
 '57 P. 729, 8. Upon the meaning of 
 
 the words aKvpa ra Trpoa-TifiTjfiara ttouI, 
 see Herald. Animadv. in Salmas. Ob- 
 serv.ad J. A. et R. iii. 3,10. 
 Z 2
 
 340 
 
 GENERAL REMARKS UPON 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 laws should remain in force with regard to them; his only 
 object being to favour certain persons connected with himself, 
 who had embezzled pubhc monies^*'; and therefore proposed, 
 that " if any one of the public debtors, by any law or decree, 
 had been, or should be, condemned to imprisonment as an addi- 
 tional punishment, either himself or some one for him should 
 be allowed to furnish sureties for the debt ; and that, when he 
 had provided sureties, if he paid the state the money for which 
 he provided the sureties, he should be released from prison : 
 but if he should not, either in his own person or through his 
 sureties, pay the money in the ninth prytaneia, that the party 
 bailed should be thrown into prison, and that the property of 
 the sureties should be forfeited to the state; but that in the 
 case of farmers of duties and their sureties, and collectors, and 
 persons renting public property and their sureties, the money 
 due should be exacted by the state according to the existing 
 laws. And if any person should become a public debtor in the 
 ninth prytaneia, he should pay the money owing either in the 
 ninth or tenth prytaneia of the following year''^^^ The right of 
 imprisoning the farmers of the duties, even without a judicial 
 sentence, which was required in other cases (imprisonment 
 being an additional punishment), is also contained in the oath 
 of the Senate of Five Hundred : '^ Neither will I imprison any 
 Athenian who produces three sureties having the same valuation 
 as himself, except he is convicted of treason against the state, 
 or of subverting the democracy, or has not paid the duty when 
 a farmer, surety, or collector^^**/^ 
 
 The object of thus imprisoning the farmers was both to pre- 
 vent the possibility of their escape, and to terrify them from 
 any irregularity in their payments, which might be the occasion 
 of much financial difficulty to the state : and for the prevention 
 
 ^^ Deraosth. passim, more particu- 
 larly p. 719, 26sqq. 
 
 *5» Demosth. p. 722, 17 sqq. See 
 Liban. in the argument, where how- 
 ever what he says in p. 696, 21, of the 
 imprisonment of the debtor in the 
 second year in reference to the ancient 
 
 law is manifestly false, and borrowed 
 from the conclusion of the law of Ti- 
 mocrates. 
 
 '^** Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 745, 
 12 sqq. Compare Andocid. de Myst. 
 p. 45, and Demosth. p. 731, 10 sq.
 
 CH. VIII.] 
 
 THE FOREGOING TAXES. 
 
 341 
 
 of inadequate security, the sureties were subject to the same 
 penalties'®'. The property of the temples was also protected 
 by similar laws; for any tenant who failed to pay the rents of 
 the lands of the gods and heroes of the tribes, himself, together 
 with his whole family and heirs, was laid under atimia, until 
 they were paid'®^ Now that Timocrates, when he mitigated 
 the severity of this law, was not so much actuated by philan- 
 thropy as by personal views, is evident from the exception 
 which he made to the prejudice of the public farmers: for since 
 these persons, as Demosthenes'®^ remarks, were exposed to 
 injury, the provisions of the new law would have been extended 
 to them with the greatest propriety: nay, this statesman was so 
 little consistent with himself, that he had formerly passed ano- 
 ther law, which provided that the offenders who had been prose- 
 cuted by an eisangelia, and condemned to pay a fine, should be 
 imprisoned until such time as they paid'®*. 
 
 From this account of the subject (which has been inten- 
 tionally given at greater detail, as in most books which contain 
 any information on this head it is mixed and confused in end- 
 less contradiction), it is evident what judgment must be passed 
 upon the passage of Ulpian'" concerning this point. " It must 
 be known,^^ he says, " that the farmers of the duties were bound 
 to furnish sureties in the very first instance, so that if they did not 
 pay until the ninth prytaneia, either they or their sureties paid 
 the double amount; and all debtors did the same: as soon as 
 they were indebted to the state, they were compelled to furnish 
 sureties, that they would pay the same before the ninth pryta- 
 neia, and remained under atimia until they paid. If however 
 the ninth prytaneia arrived, and they had not yet paid, they 
 were put in prison, fined double, and were no longer allowed to 
 find bail.^^ The grammarian evidently confounds the existing 
 ancient laws with the proposal of Timocrates, which moreover 
 
 '^^ Besides the passages already 
 quoted see the speech against Nicos- 
 tratus, p. 1254 extr. and p. 1255, 1. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Macart.p. 1069 extr. 
 
 i«^ P. 738, 20 sqq. 
 
 i«* Demosth. p. 720,721. 
 
 '^5 Ad Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 
 449. I pass over Suidas and others, 
 who have nothing peculiar or important.
 
 342 
 
 GENERAL REMARKS UPON 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 made no mention of the public farmers; the sureties provided 
 by the farmers were also responsible for the first payments 
 before the last term : the atimia^ and the right of imprisonment, 
 could be adjudged immediately after the first term had been 
 neglected; the ninth pry taneia brought with it the payment of 
 double the sum then due; and if this fine was not attended to, 
 the confiscation of property followed: whereas the proposal of 
 Timocrates took away the liability to imprisonment from the 
 public debtors (with the exception of the farmers of the duties 
 and the farmers of the landed property, together with their 
 sureties), if they could furnish security until the ninth pry ta- 
 neia, and accordingly imprisonment could not take place until 
 after the expiration of this term; it moreover wholly abolished 
 the doubling of the money in causes which were not sacred, and 
 the increasing of its amount tenfold in sacred causes, in which 
 the latter was the legal penalty for the offence^^^ 
 
 In what prytaneias the payments of the duties were 
 appointed to be made, we are not informed. According to 
 Suidas and Photius'^', two terms were fixed for the farmers of 
 the duties, the first before the beginning of their lease, and 
 afterwards a second; the money paid at the former term was 
 called the payment in advance {irpoKaTa^okrj), and that paid at 
 the latter was called the additional payment {Trpoo-Kard/SXTjfMa). 
 This statement, which is founded upon the testimony of an 
 ancient author, has much probability: thus we find that rents 
 were paid to the demi and the tribes in a similar manner, either 
 in two payments, in the first and sixth month, or in three pay- 
 ments, in the first, seventh, and eleventh months^^^: that a 
 payment took place in advance, at least coincidently with the 
 beginning of their term, can scarcely be doubted; the additional 
 payments were perhaps distributed over several prytaneias. 
 
 A difficulty however arises from the manner in which De- 
 mosthenes speaks of these additional payments {irpoo-Kara^Xri- 
 
 '*'•' Concerning these points comp, 
 also Demosth. p. 726, 22 sqq. p. 728, 
 159, p. 730, 1—4, p. 732, 24. 
 
 '^' In V. TrpoKara^oXr). According 
 
 to Lex. Seg. p. 193, 7, npoKaTa^oXrj is 
 npo TTJs irpo$€ap.ias didopevov. 
 '^^ See above chap. 2.
 
 CH. VIIlc] THE FOREGOING TAXES. 343 
 
 fiara). For in the speech against Timocrates'^' he says, in 
 order to prove that the administration was endangered by the 
 new law proposed by this person, '^ You have an excellent law, 
 which enacts, that those who are in possession of money either 
 belonging or not belonging to sacred corporations, shall deposit 
 it at the senate-house. And in case of omission, that the 
 senate may claim it by the laws which regulate the letting of 
 duties. It is by this law that the administration of public 
 affairs is carried on. For,'^ he immediately proceeds to say, ^^ if 
 the money arising from the duties is not sufficient for the uses 
 of the administration, the remaining payments are made through 
 fear of this law. Is it not then manifest, that the whole fabric 
 of the state must be dissolved, if the payments of the duties {at 
 Twv reXojv Kara^okal) are insufficient by a considerable sum 
 for the demands of the administration? Nor even in such a 
 case as this could they be obtained until the conclusion of the 
 year. And if neither the senate nor the courts of justice are 
 authorized to imprison those who fail to pay the remaining 
 portions, but the defaulters are allowed to provide sureties until 
 the ninth prj'taneia, what will become of us during the inter- 
 vening eight ?^^ 
 
 In this passage the additional payments are opposed 
 to the duties. The laws relating to the letting of duties 
 appear to have been only applied to them^^", and the duties 
 themselves were not paid in full until about the end of the 
 year. If this representation is correct, I confess that I do 
 not understand what these additional payments can be. By 
 the sacred and public money, which had been received by pri- 
 vate individuals from the state, nothing else can be meant than 
 rents of duties and lands, and fines which were owing to the 
 public. Among these the additional payments must be included, 
 according to Demosthenes' own words. That they were fines is 
 extremely improbable, if we may judge from the force of the 
 word. What then can they be, except unpaid rents of duties 
 and lands? Are we therefore to suppose that Demosthenes, 
 when he speaks of duties, only alluded to the sums that were 
 
 P. 730, 731. '70 On this point comp. also p. 732, 1, 2.
 
 344 FEES AND PAYMENTS [bK. III. 
 
 paid in advance ? This hypothesis is hardly credible, especially 
 as he again says, that the duties were paid in full about the end 
 of the year. Or was this last remark added on the supposition 
 that the first payments of the public farmers were not, according 
 to the law of Timocrates, to be made until the ninth prytaneia, 
 as the farmers were to provide security up to that period? This 
 would be an unheard-of piece of sophistry; for Timocrates 
 particularly excludes the farmers of duties from the benefits of 
 his new law. I am therefore forced to confess my ignorance 
 of what Demosthenes means by those additional payments, 
 and must leave the statement of Suidas to rest upon its own 
 authority, in the hope that some acuter person may solve the 
 difficulty which I have pointed out. 
 
 Chapter IX. 
 
 Fees and Payments upon Legal Proceedings, Prytaneia, 
 Parastasis, 
 
 The second head of the public revenue comprehends the justice 
 fees and fines. 
 
 This source of income was not by any means inconsiderable. 
 Among the advantages which Sparta might expect to gain by 
 the fortification of Decelea, Alcibiades enumerates the loss which 
 the Athenians would sustain of the revenues from the courts of 
 Justice^'^; as a cessation of justice was caused by the existence 
 of a war in the country. The circumstance of Alcibiades using 
 this as an argument in favour of his proposal, proves that the 
 sum lost would not have been trifling. The productiveness of 
 these imposts was increased by the obligation of the allies to 
 try their causes in Athens, which regulation, inasmuch as it 
 
 '^^ Thucyd. vi. 91. The Scholiast j he probably means ylrevdeyypacfyris, the 
 upon this place ignorantly and inac- action for false enrolment among the 
 curately mentions the fines in seve- | public debtors), for malversations of am- 
 ral laM'suits, as e. g. in the action ; bassadors {Trapanpeo-^eias), and leaving 
 for bribery (ScopodoKiai), assault ; the army (Xfinoo-TpaTiov) : whereas 
 (v^pecos), sycophancy, adultery, false j upon all these offences much severer 
 registration {\j/cvboypa(f>ias, by which I penalties than fines could be imposed.
 
 CIl. IX.] UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 345 
 
 increased the amount of the dicasts' wages, and consequently 
 contributed largely to the support of the citizens, was of the 
 highest importance. 
 
 The justice fees and fines which here come into considera- 
 tion, are, in the first place, the four mentioned together by 
 Pollux ^^*, parastasis, epobelia, prytaneia, and paracatabole, of 
 which the first and third always accrued to the state, the fourth 
 probably in certain cases, the second never: to which may be 
 added, the damages assessed for offences {rifirjiMaTa), if they 
 were estimated in money, and the fines imposed by law upon 
 unsuccessful plaintiffs or accusers. 
 
 I will first consider the prytaneia {irpvTaveta), These, as is 
 well known, both parties were obhged to deposit in court, before 
 the beginning of the suit — not however if the case was referred 
 to an arbitrator — like the Roman sacramentum: if the plaintiff 
 omitted this payment, the officers who introduced the cause 
 {ol elcraycojets) quashed the suit; the party which lost the cause 
 paid both prytaneia, that is to say, his own were forfeited, and 
 he replaced the sum which had been paid by the successful 
 party '^'. The amount was fixed according to the standard of 
 the cause, in the pecuniary assessment; in a suit for sums of 
 from 100 to 1000 drachmas, 3 drachmas was the amount to be 
 paid by each party; for sums of from 1001 to 10,000 drachmas, 
 30 drachmas'^*; for larger sums probably in the same progres- 
 sion. With regard to suits for less than 100 drachmas, nothing 
 is stated; probably no prytaneia were paid for them, a case to 
 which Valesius appears with justice to refer a proverb preserved 
 in Hesychius^^^ 
 
 It is to be observed, that the statement of Pollux is con- 
 firmed by two cases in judicial pleadings which are still extant. 
 
 i7i viii. 37. I ''* Hesychius in v. avcv 7rpvTav€ia>Vj 
 
 '7' Demosth. c. Everg. et Mnesib. [ Vales.adHarpocrat.p.l65,ed.Gronov. 
 
 yjrevdo^. in the passage which will be : Matthiae on the other hand (MiscelL 
 
 immediately quoted, Pollux viii. 38, 
 Harpocration in v. Trpvravela, and 
 thence Suidas, Photius, and Schol. 
 Aristoph. Nub. 1139. 
 '^* PoUux \iii. 38. 
 
 Philog. vol. i. p. 262,) refers this to the 
 diKT] KaKaa-eois : tlie 8ikt) v^pecos might 
 be also understood : but of this here- 
 after.
 
 346 FEES AND PAYMENTS [bK. III. 
 
 Callimachus, as mentioned in Isocrates, had instituted a suit for 
 10,000 drachmas against the dient of this orator, who defended 
 himself with a paragraphe; but he afterwards reUnquished it in 
 order that he might not be obhged to pay the epobeha, which 
 he must have done if he did not obtain a fifth part of the votes; 
 subsequently, however, having gained over the authorities to 
 his side, he again set the cause on foot, as he now thought that 
 he had only to fear the danger of losing the prytaneia'^'. The 
 defendant, on the other hand, makes use of a law of Archinus, 
 which was passed under the following circumstances. After the 
 return of the people from the Pireeus, many citizens had been 
 accused before the people contrary to the act of amnesty, on the 
 charge of having connected themselves with the aristocratical 
 party; in order therefore to secure these persons against fri- 
 volous actions, he enacted that if any one should be accused 
 contrar)^ to the oath of amnesty, he could defend himself by a 
 paragraphe, and whichever of the two parties should in that case 
 be found guilty, was to pay the epobelia to the other. The 
 orator, however, endeavours to show that CalUmachus was vio- 
 lating the act of amnesty, in order that he should not merely be 
 exposed to the danger of losing the 30 drachmas ^'^ In this 
 case these 30 drachmas are evidently the prytaneia: Isocrates^ 
 client, however, only reckons the prytaneia for one party, 
 w^hich would be due to him from Callimachus, in case the latter 
 person lost the cause; of the other prytaneia, which Callimachus 
 had already paid, he takes no account, since his only object is 
 to form an antithesis between the additional payments which 
 would be made in either case; these being the prytaneia to be 
 restored to the successful party, in case no paragraphe was insti- 
 tuted, and the prytaneia together with the epobelia, which would 
 be paid by one party after the introduction of a paragraphe. 
 
 Another clearer case occurs in the speech against Euergus 
 and Mnesibulus for false testimony, in the works of Demos- 
 thenes ^^^. The plaintiff had been cast in an action for an 
 
 '76 UapaypacfiT) c. Callimach. 5 — 7. ' the sum in both places is 1403 drachmas 
 
 ' '7 Ibid. 1—2, also 9 sqq. | 2 oboli, of wliich nothing can be made. 
 
 ''8 P. 1 158, 20 sqq. Cf. p. 1162, 20. j It is a corruption from XHHHAIHII 
 
 In a recent manuscript of no authority, ! into XHHH HI 11 II. Petit as usual
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 
 
 347 
 
 assault {hiKT) alKias) brought against him by Theophemus, 
 which was connected with a cross action, both parties having 
 come forward as plaintiffs; and he was forced to pay 1313 
 drachmas 2 oboli to him: in this sum the epobelia and the pry- 
 taneia amounting to 30 drachmas are expressly included : the 
 fine was doubtless a round sum, and probably amounted to 1100 
 drachmas, upon which supposition the epobelia came to 183 
 drachmas 2 oboli. 
 
 From this it is evident that the idea of some grammarians' % 
 that the prytaneia were the tenth part of the estimated damages, 
 does not deserve the least credit; especially as we are enabled 
 easily to explain how they fell into this error. They state that 
 the prytaneia were deposited by the plaintiff alone, whereas they 
 were paid by both parties; but in the case of a suit in which any 
 party claimed an inheritance or an heiress, the paracatabole was 
 paid by the plaintiff alone, which amounted to the tenth part of 
 the valuation; it was with this payment that they confounded the 
 prytaneia. This confusion is particularly apparent in the state- 
 ments of Suidas and the Scholiast to Aristophanes: the latter'"" 
 informs us, that the prytaneia, which amounted to the tenth part 
 of the valuation, were also called paracatabole; the former'^' 
 applies the statement that the paracatabole was the tenth part 
 of the valuation, to the prytaneia in the Clouds of Aristophanes, 
 and particularly mentions the identity of the two. Both these 
 
 (Leg. Att. V. 1, 3) confuses the whole 
 passage. Palmerius understood it 
 rightly, but without correcting the er- 
 rors of the common reading. Instead 
 of yiKias fiev Kal eKarov dpuxfJ-ns Koi 
 Tpeis Koi dvco o/3oXa) rrjv enco^eXiav, 
 which is manifestly imj^erfect, should 
 be written ;^iXias' fiev Kal eKarov SpaX" 
 fias TTju KaradiKT^v, dydorjKovra de Kai 
 eKarov dpaxpas Kal rpels, Kal dva> o/3oXcb 
 rrjv eVcoiSeXiai', although perhaps the 
 right place of the words Kal rpels 
 is before bpaxp-as. With regard to 
 the position of the words, which was 
 chosen for a reason which will be 
 easily perceived, compare Dinarchus 
 ap. Dionys. Halicarn. in vit. Dinarch. 
 
 Xpvaiov pev ararrjpas oydorjKOvra Kal 
 8iaKoa-iovs Kal nevre. The epobelia in 
 the cross-suit was not paid from the 
 timema fixed by the adversary, but 
 from that at which the party himself 
 had assessed his opponent: in this 
 case, however, both were manifestly 
 the same, as the accurate coincidence 
 of the numbers shows. 
 
 ^79 Pollux ibid. Hesychius, Ammo- 
 nius, and thence Thomas Magister in 
 V. npvravelov. 
 
 '^'^ Schol. Nub. 1258. 
 
 '^^ Suid. in napaKara^oXr}. Con- 
 cerning these errors comp. also Petit 
 Leg. Att. V. 1, 9.
 
 348 
 
 FEES AND PAYMENTS 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 writers are ignorant enough to assert that the creditors paid a 
 tenth part of the sum in suits relating to monies owing to them, 
 which were called prytaneia^^*: which account is in the first 
 place censurable for stating that the tenth part was always paid, 
 and in the second place for mentioning the prytaneia alone in 
 the Clouds of Aristophanes^". It should however be observed, 
 that this confusion of the prytaneia with the paracatabole is 
 derived from an idiomatical ambiguity of terms; for when used 
 in its wider sense, the latter expression denotes any sum of 
 money paid in court; hence again, the Etymologist explains 
 the parastasis and paracatabole as identical^". The prytaneia 
 may accordingly be included under the paracatabole in its more 
 general meaning, but they are not for that reason the same as 
 the paracatabole in its more limited signification ; and still less 
 can the latter, as Maussac supposed, be classed among the 
 prytaneia. 
 
 With the prytaneia the parastasis [irapdcTacn'^, irapaKard- 
 araa-is) was intimately connected. The pay of the arbitrators 
 or diaetetae was called by this name^^^, with which we have no 
 concern in this place, as it was paid directly into the hands of 
 the disetetse, and not into the" public treasury : and to this pay- 
 ment the words of Harpocration refer, when he explains the 
 parastasis to be a drachma, which was deposited by persons 
 who carried on private law-suits. On the other hand, there 
 was another parastasis of unknown, but probably very small, 
 amount, and the same in all cases: perhaps this one was not 
 more than a drachma, and was doubtless received by the 
 state' ^'. According to Aristotle''^, it was paid before a public 
 action to the thesmothetae, if a foreigner was accused of 
 
 ^^ Schol. Vesp. 657. Suidas in npv- 
 ravelov and npoKaTa^oX^. 
 
 '^^ Vs. 1181, 1257. The Scholiast 
 on the Clouds (vs. 1192) says that the 
 prytaneia were a drachma paid into 
 the public treasury, confounding them 
 with the parastasis. 
 
 '^^ Isocrat. c. Lochit. 3, with the 
 notes of Valesius ad Harpocrat. De- 
 mosth. c. Tanticnet. p. 978, 20; Har- 
 
 pocration, Photius, and Suidas, in napa- 
 Kara/SoXi), Etymol. in TrapaKaTaa-Tacris. 
 
 '^^ See book ii. ch. 15. 
 
 '^^ From which the statement of the 
 Scholiast on Aristophanes (Nub. 1 192), 
 quoted above in note 183, may pro- 
 bably be explained. 
 
 '"' Ath. Polit. ap. Harpocrat. Phot, 
 in napdcTTacns. See Pollux viii. 8; 
 Phot, in napaKaTLKjTad IS .
 
 CH. 
 
 IX.] 
 
 UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 
 
 349 
 
 having illegally introduced himself among the citizens (ypa<l>r} 
 ^evtas), or was charged, after an accusation of this kind, with 
 having obtained a favourable verdict by bribery {ypacprj Bojpo- 
 ^eviasf); again in suits concerning false enrolment among the 
 public debtors {yjrevB€yypa(j)rj<;), for false summoning (yjrevBo- 
 KXrjalas), conspiracy (ffovXevo-eaysf), false erasement from the 
 list of the public debtors (aypacfyiov), and for adultery {/jloi- 
 'X^elas). This is not a complete enumeration of the public 
 actions ^^^; the author however appears only to have quoted 
 them as examples, and it can hardly be doubted that the para- 
 stasis was paid in all other indictments {ypa<l)al) brought before 
 the thesmothetse, and in all other public actions. It appears, 
 however, to have been deposited by the plaintiff alone, for the 
 purpose of calling out his adversary, and of introducing the 
 action. 
 
 It is very certain that parastasis and prytaneia were never 
 paid together; for both of them had the same object, viz. of 
 commencing the cause: it may however be well inquired, in 
 what cases the one or the other payment was made, an inves- 
 tigation which has not as yet been undertaken by any writer. 
 Omitting then the parastasis of the disetetae, I assert, that in 
 private law-suits {IBUc BUat) prytaneia alone, and no para- 
 stasis, were paid, and conversely that in the public actions (Blfcai 
 hTjfioalaL^ KaT7]yopiai^ ypa(f>al) parastasis alone, and no pryta- 
 neia. We even learn from examples, that prytaneia were paid 
 in private and parastasis in public causes : thus the former 
 were deposited in cases of debt ; as, for example, Strepsiades' 
 creditor in the Clouds threatens him with depositing the pry- 
 taneia'^'. This regulation is quite intelligible. All private 
 causes, with the exception of those which were instituted for 
 assaults, referred to wrongs for which fines had been appointed 
 by law''% so that the latter could not be altered, except that in 
 actions for damages the plaintiff so far appointed the fine, that 
 he estimated his own injury'"'; in which case an alteration in 
 
 i«8 See Matthise Miscell. Philog. 
 vol. i. p. 247 sqq. 
 '«9 Vs. 1257. 
 '^^ The word Tifirj^a is here trans- 
 
 lated by fine, whether it had the nature 
 of damages or of punishment. 
 '^' See below chap. II.
 
 350 FEES AND PAYMENTS [bK. III. 
 
 the estimate could only have been made by petition, and mostly 
 with the consent of the plaintiff. Here then the prytaneia 
 could be fixed with certainty. 
 
 Again, in a private cause the plaintiff claimed either a sum 
 of money or money^s worth from the defendant, which moreover 
 he was himself to receive : it was therefore fair that he should 
 be subject to the payment of justice fees. But in pubHc actions 
 the determination of the prytaneia would have been liable 
 to great difficulties, and in many cases have been wholly 
 impossible. For if either loss of life, banishment, confiscation 
 of property, or atimia, were assigned as the penalty, it would 
 have been impossible to estimate the amount of the prytaneia, 
 as they were always fixed according to the money in litigation. 
 The fines in pubUc causes were also subject to considerable and 
 frequent alterations, and if the payment of the prytaneia took 
 place in cases of this description, they could only have been 
 fixed according to the estimate of the plaintiff in his pleadings ; 
 but as we find no mention of any such arrangement, we may 
 safely conclude that it did not exist. When for example 
 ^schines, in his action against Ctesiphon for illegal proceedings 
 {ypacj^rj TrapavofMcov), estimates the damages at 50 talents, the 
 prytaneia of both parties would together have amounted to a 
 talent, the payment of which would have fallen upon the losing 
 party: but nothing of the kind is any where alluded to, although 
 the far inferior loss of 1000 drachmas, which the plaintiff was 
 to pay in case he did not obtain the fifth part of the votes, 
 is repeatedly mentioned. 
 
 Moreover the public plaintiff did not pursue his own advan- 
 tage; and if he gained the cause, the state, or whoever was the 
 injured party, and not the accuser, received the fine. It would 
 not therefore have been just that he should pay any prytaneia. 
 It was also against the interest of the state to throw difficulties 
 in the way of public actions, by compelling the deposit of pry- 
 taneia. The only payment required in the case which has been 
 just quoted, was the penalty of the thousand drachmas imposed 
 upon the plaintiff for the purpose of restraining frivolous accu- 
 sations ; and in cases in which a private money suit was mixed 
 wdth a public action, the epobelia was exacted : the parastasis
 
 CH. IX.] UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 351 
 
 however appears to have had a symbolical meaning, and to have 
 signified that the cause was commenced. In every other case 
 the state decided all public actions gratis, as they related to mat- 
 ters concerning its own interest, and the fines were afterwards 
 sufficient to cover the expense. 
 
 There were, however, some public actions from which the 
 plaintiff, in case he gained his cause, obtained some advantage 
 at the same time that he prosecuted the offender ; in such cases 
 as these the plaintiff paid the prytaneia for one party, but the 
 plaintiff alone. Thus a law enacted, that whoever dug up olive- 
 trees, excepting upon particular occasions, should pay to the 
 state a fine of 100 drachmas for each tree, and an equal sum to 
 the plaintiff : "the plaintiff however was to pay the prytaneia 
 for his own share^^^^^ This was a public action; for the interest 
 of the community, and not of any individual, was damnified by 
 the diminution of the culture of olives, and all persons were at 
 liberty to accuse. Now since the payment of the prytaneia is 
 expressly enjoined in this law, it is manifest that they were not 
 commonly required in public actions, since otherwise it would 
 have been unnecessary to insert this clause. The reason how- 
 ever why the plaintiff alone was bound to pay them is, that he 
 might derive individual advantage from the introduction of the 
 cause, in case he was successful: so that considered in this light 
 it was his private suit: thus the Roman law made the injury of 
 the praetorian album a private cause [causa privata), although 
 the privilege of accusation was free to any person [in causa popu- 
 lari). The defendant however did not deposit any prytaneia, 
 inasmuch as he did not damnify the private interest of the 
 plaintiff, and on his side the cause was entirely public. 
 
 There was also another kind of public action, in which the 
 plaintiff might advance his own interests, while at the same 
 time he endeavoured to maintain the rights of the state. This 
 was the phasis (or information), which form of proceeding might 
 be instituted either in the case of robbery of public property, 
 or in offences concerning trade, custom duties, and mines, syco- 
 
 '^^ UpyTavela Se TiOero) 6 fitwKcoi/ rov avrov fiepovs, Lex. ap. Deniostli. c. 
 Macart. p. 1074, 19.
 
 352 
 
 FEES AND PAYMENTS 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 phancy, and offences against wards; and in this form of action 
 all persons had the right of accusing, even if they were not the 
 parties injured. If a person who had not been injured came 
 forward as accuser in a phasis, and if he only undertook the 
 action as the representative of the pubhc, and not as his private 
 suit, the estimated damages were not awarded to the plaintiff, if 
 he gained the cause from the defendant, but to the injured 
 party'"; to the state, for example, if the property of the state 
 was injured; to the farmers of the customs, if the custom 
 duties had been fraudulently evaded; to the orphans, if the 
 property of orphans had been embezzled. Consequently an 
 accuser of this kind paid only the parastasis, and no pry^taneia ; 
 but in order to repress frivolous accusations, the accuser was 
 subjected to the risk of the thousand drachmas, and on certain 
 occasions to the epobelia, if he did not obtain the fifth part of 
 the votes'^*. 
 
 But what were the regulations if the injured party himself 
 came forward an accuser? In this case two different methods 
 may be conceived to have existed. A case which would justify 
 the institution of a phasis, admitted of being viewed in a double 
 light; and the plaintiff, whom it individually concerned, could, 
 as I am convinced, select which of the two he would adopt. 
 Thus, for example, redress might be obtained for an assault 
 either by a private [hUy] alKias) or a public action [hiKT] or 
 ypa(l>7j v^pecos), according as the plaintiff chose: so as we learn 
 from Demosthenes, the law intentionally allowed in very many 
 cases not two only, but even four different methods of proceed- 
 ing, in order that every person might choose according to his 
 disposition and circumstances: for instance, a person might in- 
 stitute a private action for a theft of property exceeding 50 
 drachmas, and among public actions, the common action, the 
 aTraycoyr) and the ephegesis; there were also four different 
 forms of proceeding in a case of impiety, and so with almost 
 every other offence '*'. The correctness of this assertion is 
 
 '»3 Pollux viii. 41,48. 
 
 '«* See below chap. 10, 12. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Androt. p. 601. On 
 
 this point see more particularly He- 
 rald. Animadv. iv. 7, 8.
 
 CH. IX.] UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 353 
 
 proved by the spirit of the whole Athenian law. In the same 
 manner the law, in an instance in which private property had 
 been damaged, either allowed a case which justified the proce- 
 dure by phasis, to be in fact brought on as a phasis or a public 
 suit (which course a person who had not received any injury, in 
 case he wished to come forw^ard as accuser, was always com- 
 pelled to take), or the injured party was at liberty only to found 
 a private actioa upon it, for the purpose of prosecuting his own 
 rights. By the former method of proceeding the plaintiif 
 brought the defendant into greater hazard, as the latter was sub- 
 ject to the penalty not only of a fine, but also of imprisonment 
 and death : at the same time he exposed himself to the risk of 
 the thousand drachmas, and also of the epobelia, if he did not 
 obtain the fifth part of the votes. In the latter case the defen- 
 dant was exposed to less risk, and the plaintifi* was not subject 
 to the loss of the thousand drachmas, but only of the epobelia. 
 Now with regard to the prytaneia, we can hardly suppose that 
 they were required in the first case, as the injured party came 
 forward solely in the character of public accuser, and the fine 
 which he received would have been equally paid to him if ano- 
 ther person had been plaintiff: in the latter case, however, pry- 
 taneia were unquestionably required, as the cause was merely a 
 private suit. 
 
 It is probable that, unless some particular cause of animosity 
 or zeal existed, the method of the private suit was generally 
 preferred; and we have still two law-suits extant, which might 
 have justified a phasis, and were nevertheless instituted as pri- 
 vate causes. Pollux expressly states that the action against 
 guardians {Zlkti eTTiTpoTrrjf;) was a public suit, and adds, that 
 any person who washed it was at liberty to prosecute the guar- 
 dian in behalf of the injured orphans '^^; and yet in another 
 place he calls it a private suit^^^: so again the author of the 
 Lexicon Rhetoricum considers the action for the omission of 
 the letting of orphans^ property as a phasis, and at the same 
 
 ^^^ Pollux (viii. 35) calls it the diKt] \ ^^^ y[[i 31^ Heraldus Animadv. in 
 (TTLTpoirris hrj^ocrla. ^E^tjv yap tw jBov- Salmas. Observ. iii. 4, 5, also considers 
 Xo/xfi/6) ypd(Pca6ai tov enLTponou virep j that the biKr) eniTpoTrrjs was a private 
 Ta>v ddiKoviMevcov opcpavcou. I suit. 
 
 2 A
 
 354 
 
 FEES AND PAYMENTS [bK. III. 
 
 time as a private suit'^^ and it is also cited by Pollux, together 
 with the action against guardians, among the private suits^'^ 
 The law-suit of Demosthenes, detailed in the speeches against 
 Aphobus, which have been placed by the arrangers of his works 
 among the private orations, is an action against guardians. Are 
 we then to suppose that these persons were deceived in a whole 
 set of speeches so important in the history of Demosthenes? 
 It is hio-hly improbable that they should have committed so 
 great an error, although it is true that they have incorrectly 
 classed two other speeches^"". It is indeed evident from the 
 tenour of the speech itself, that the action was not a phasis, but 
 merely a private suit. Demosthenes frequently complains that 
 he is exposed to the risk of the epobeha, to which his property 
 was only just sufficient, and which should not in fairness have 
 applied in his case'''. Again, if the action had been a phasis, 
 he would have spoken of the thousand drachmas, which must 
 have been paid in the same case to which the epobelia applied. 
 But of this payment he says not a word. Or are we to sup- 
 pose, that in the action against guardians the phasis itself, which 
 in all other cases was a pubhc suit, became a private one, with 
 this difference only, that any person had the liberty of accusing? 
 This is apparently the notion which the author of the Lexicon 
 Rhetoricum had formed of this point, as he calls the phasis a 
 species of public and private action, and the latter with refer- 
 ence to the omission of the letting of orphans' property; his 
 
 out the meaning of oIkos correctly in 
 his Animadv. in Salmas. Observat. iii. 
 6, 10. 
 
 ^^^ In the speeches against Nico- 
 stratus and against Theocrines, neither 
 of which, however, is by Demosthenes. 
 The latter was considered by Calli- 
 
 ^3« Lex. Seg. p. 313, cf. p. 315; 
 Etymol. in v. (pdais, Phot, in v. (jydais, 
 particularly in the second article, and 
 Epitome of Harpocration, quoted by 
 the commentators upon Pollux viii. 47. 
 
 ^^^ To this action the w^ords of Pol- 
 lux viii. 31 {^Iktj) /xicr^too-fcoy oXkov 
 Bhould be referred. Iludtwalcker is ' machus to be the work of Demos- 
 incorrect in supposing (von den Dia- ' thenes, but Dionysius and the greater 
 teten, p. 143,) that the dUr] {xLadoiaews ' number of authorities include it in the 
 oIkov is the same as the action for the ' works of Dinarchus, and justly give it 
 payment of house-rent {bUr] (volkIov), a place among the public orations, 
 an error into which he was probably See the Life of Dinarchus by Diony- 
 led from the difference between olkos sius. 
 
 and olKia in the Athenian law having ' ^^^ P. 834, 25, p. 835, 14, p. 841, 22, 
 escaped him. Ileraldus has pointed p. 880, 9.
 
 CII IX.] UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 355 
 
 statement^ however, is probably founded upon a confusion, the 
 origin of which was, that the subject of a phasis could equally 
 be the subject of a private cause; and that it was the wish of 
 the government that offences connected with guardianship 
 should be treated as public actions, as well as offences relating 
 to harbours, custom duties, and mines, and sycophancy, in 
 order to give greater protection to orphans. And it is remark- 
 able that Photius, who for the most part coincides with the 
 Lexicon Rhetoricum, opposes the phasis regarding the property 
 of orphans, to the public actions, but yet does not distinctly 
 call it a private suit; so that the grammarians do not themselves 
 appear to have formed any precise notion of the subject. It 
 may therefore be supposed that as, in the Roman law, the actio 
 tutelce of the ward against the guardian, at the end of the guar- 
 dianship, for a restitution of the property taken from him 
 during the minority, was a private suit, and the actio suspecti of 
 a third person against the guardian who acted dishonestly during 
 the tutelage was a quasi-public [quasi publica) suit, so in the 
 Athenian law, a distinction of the following nature existed be- 
 tween the actions against guardians; viz., the public action was 
 the phasis, not being however, as in the Roman law, limited to 
 a third person, and to the continuance of the guardianship*"^ 
 and the private suit was the hiKrj iinrpoTrrjs and /jLcadojaecos olkov. 
 The grammarians then appear, in the first place, to be in error 
 when they call the Bikt] eVtTpoTr?}? and /niadcoa-eco^ olkov a public 
 action^''% and secondly, when they call the phasis in actions 
 
 '■^"^ A public action against a frau- ; spirit of the Athenian law, by which 
 dulent guardian is extant in the ora- the greatest liberty in the selection of 
 tion of Lysias against Diogeiton, where the mode of proceeding was allowed, 
 he speaks of the extreme of danger I "^"^ It may be easily perceived how 
 (eaxaroi Kivdvvoi, p. 893 ad fin.) which ' Pollux, who alone, as far as I remem- 
 alludes to the penalty of death. It is ber, calls tlie 8iKr] eVtrpoTr?}? a public 
 instituted by a third person, but after | suit, was led into this notion. For 
 the conclusion of the guardianship, and [ after having correctly mentioned the 
 
 diKT] eVtrpoTT^f and fita-doicreois olkov in 
 the enumeration of the private suits, 
 he returns to it only incidentally in 
 viii. 35, in the words aTrpoirraa-iov 8i 
 Kara tcov ov vefjLOUTCov TrpocrraTTjv fxeroi- 
 Kcov dXX' avTT) (as should be read for 
 
 2 A 2 
 
 the passing of the accounts. That the 
 injured party was also empowered to 
 bring on this kind of action, I do not 
 find anywhere expressly stated ; but it 
 can hardly be doubted that such was 
 the case, if we mav judge from the
 
 356 FEES AND PAYMENTS [bK. III. 
 
 against guardians a private suit; excepting that this phasis, by 
 reason of its double relation^ both to the injury of individuals 
 and to that of the state, may be considered as a public and at 
 the same time as a private action, and by this means the account 
 of the grammarians may be in some measure justified : whereas 
 it is extremely improbable that the public action or the phasis, 
 and the private suit, were both called hUrj iTrirpoiTri^ and fita- 
 daxrecos oXkov, 
 
 There is a corresponding resemblance between the proceed- 
 ings against Aphobus, and the law-suit detailed in the speech 
 against Bionysodorus. The defendant, as is plain from the 
 charges of the accuser, had not only injured him, but also trans- 
 gressed the commercial laws; consequently he might have been 
 prosecuted for this latter offence by a phasis; yet it is manifest 
 from the whole speech, that this matter was taken up as a pri- 
 vate suit, and we therefore hear nothing of the possible loss of 
 the thousand drachmas, but only that the plaintiff, in case of 
 failure, will be forced to pay the epobelia^"'^. We do not, 
 indeed, in either of these two law-suits, find any mention of the 
 prytaneia, an omission in which there is nothing remarkable; 
 for their loss and restitution was so much a matter of course, 
 as they were deposited in all private causes with the excep- 
 tion of the private action for an assault, that no allusion to 
 this payment need be expected. Apollodorus also in the first 
 oration against Stephanus^**^, in an action for debt, in which we 
 know with certainty from Aristophanes that the pr^'taneia were 
 always required, only remarks that he should have to pay the 
 epobelia in addition, silently implying the loss and restitution 
 of the prytaneia. 
 
 avTT]) fxev brj^oaia, uxTTTCp Kai t] Trjs em- 
 
 TpoTrrjs. 'E|^y yap roj (3ov\opevco ypd- 
 
 (})ea6ai ruv eniTponov vnep twv abiKOv- 
 
 fxevcov dp(f)ava>v. Here it occuired to 
 
 him accidentally, that the guardian 
 
 might be prosecuted by any person, 
 
 \{z. by a phasis, and thus he thought 
 
 it necessary to remark, that the bUr] 
 
 eTTtrpoTT^? was a public suit, although j (TrcolBeXiav. 
 
 he had before stated it to be a private | 
 
 suit. The first account he appears 
 however to have derived from good 
 authority; the accidental observation 
 evidently came from his own head, 
 and therefore it deserves but little 
 credit. 
 
 ■^^^ r, 1284, 2. 
 
 '^^^ P. 1103, 15, npoa-ocfjXoiv be Trjv
 
 CH. IX.] UPOX LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 357 
 
 Heiresses [eiriKXripoL) were under the peculiar protection 
 of the state. If, therefore, any person laid claim to an heiress 
 whom another person wished to marry, as having a better right 
 to her, he was compelled to pay the parastasis as in a public 
 action^*'^ One description of actions, viz., the eisangelia for 
 mal-treatment of the helpless, for example, of an heiress, of 
 parents on the part of children, and orphans on the part of the 
 guardians [KaKciiaews einKkrjpov, yovicov, opcpavcov), which was 
 commenced before the archon eponymus, received from the 
 state a considerable preference, in the exemption from pryta- 
 neia and parastasis; and even if the accuser did not obtain a 
 single vote, he was not, according to Isseus, exposed to any 
 risk*''^ It is also to be observed, that this was a pubhc suit, 
 since every person was allowed to accuse either by instituting 
 an eisangeha^"% or a common indictment {ypacpijY^^i and the 
 probable reason why Pollux*^" enumerates it among the private 
 suits, is, that for the same wrong which justified a public action, 
 the party injured (for example, the ward after the cessation of 
 his minority) could seek redress by a private one. 
 
 Another particular exception also existed in the actions for 
 assault. Isocrates mentions*' ', that public and private suits 
 [ypacfial koI hiKai) might be instituted for an assault [v^pis) 
 without depositing any sacramentum {'jrapaKaTa/SoXi]), which 
 preference existed in this case alone. In this statement there 
 is a trifling discrepancy with Iseeus, who mentions that the 
 eisangelia before the archon was the only one devoid of hazard. 
 According to Isocrates, however, the private action for an 
 assault at least, was completely free from risk, whatever might 
 have been the case with the public suit, which, if this exemp- 
 
 206 Andoc. de Myst. p. CO. j ^ " viii. 31. 
 
 ^'^^ Isseus de Pyi-rhi Hered. p. 44, 
 45, and thence Harpocration in v. 
 elcrayyeXia. 
 
 208 Isseus ut sup. Compare De- 
 
 21*0. Lochit. 3. See Vales ad Har- 
 pociat. in v. napaKaTa(3o\f)y Sigon. R. 
 A. ii. 6. Whoever wishes to see a 
 full account of the diKTj alKias and 
 
 mosth. c. Panta^net. p. 979 sqq. He- ! v^pecos, may find it in Heraldus Ob- 
 rald. Animadv. in Salmas. Observat. serv. et Emend, c. 46—48, and in his 
 iii. 14, 4, Matthia? Miscell. Philog. p. Animadv. in Salmas. Obser. ad I. A. 
 234 sq. et R. ii 9, sq<i. and iii. passim. 
 
 209 
 
 Orat c. Theocrin. p. 1332, 14.
 
 358 FEES AND PAYMENTS [CK. III. 
 
 tioii did not extend to it,, would have subjected the accuser to 
 the loss of the thousand drachmas: unless the epobelia applied 
 in the first case, if the plaintiff had not the fifth part of the 
 votes on his side, a point as to which we are at least wholly 
 uninformed. Nor was it only in actions for assault that 
 no sacramentum was necessary, since it was not paid in the 
 eisangelia above-mentioned. Whether, however, the state- 
 ments of the two orators can or cannot be reconciled with one 
 another, thus much is certain, that in the action for an assault 
 the accuser paid nothing for the introduction of the cause, as 
 M'ell as in the case of which Isseus speaks: which was so 
 arranged in order to give to the poor the means of protecting 
 themselves against the oppression of the rich and noble, a pre- 
 ference founded upon a democratic, and we may boldly say, a 
 truly humane principle; and for this reason also the prytaneia, 
 which were paid in all other private causes, were not required 
 in private actions for assault. Notwithstanding this, the pay- 
 ment of the prytaneia took place in the action for assault 
 contained in the speech against Euergus and Mnesibulus. 
 
 This law-suit, which we have already noticed, was, however, 
 of a mixed kind; and from this circumstance the solution of 
 this difficulty may be derived. The client of the Pseudo- 
 Demosthenes and his adversary Theophemus had beaten one 
 another with cudgels: one of them instituted a private action 
 for an assault [Blkt] alKias), and the other person did pre- 
 cisely the same; it was therefore a cross-suit {avrcypatf)!^). 
 But the latter method of proceeding was particularly guarded 
 against by the fear of the epobelia, as it would have given rise 
 to vexatious persecution from one party'^'''; and for the same 
 reason the preference granted to the action for an assault, viz., 
 that it should be introduced without any payment of money, 
 ceased at the very moment when the suspicion of a vexatious 
 intention was caused by the introduction of a cross-suit. The 
 first plaintiff, who merely instituted an action for assault, 
 paid no prytaneia; but the plaintiff in the cross action was 
 compelled to deposit them; by doing which he at the same 
 
 Sec below, chap. U>.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 UPON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 
 
 359 
 
 time entailed the payment of them upon the first plaintiff, who 
 by this time had become defendant. If either party lost his 
 cause without having the fifth part of the votes on his side — 
 as, for example, the client of Demosthenes in the speech above 
 quoted — in the first place his prytaneia were forfeited to the 
 state, and he was obliged to replace the prytaneia of the suc- 
 cessful party: in the second place, he had to pay the fine to his 
 adversary: and lastly, he had to pay to the opponent the epo- 
 beha for the fine at which he had assessed his injury. 
 
 These monies, the prytaneia and the parastasis, were used, 
 like the parastasis of the disetetse, for paying the wages of the 
 dicasts; of the prytaneia in particular, as being the most 
 important, it is mentioned, that they were applied to the pay- 
 ment of the courts of justice^ '^ The prytaneia have therefore 
 been compared with the fees of the Roman courts; and this 
 analogy has been supported by a passage in Aristophanes, 
 which, however, does not prove that the dicasts received the 
 prytaneia at Athens immediately, as the Romans received their 
 fees^'"*. On the other hand, Joseph Scaliger^'* has started the 
 singular notion, that the corresponding payment at Rome were 
 not the justice fees, but the sportula which was given by the 
 nobles of Rome to their clients, in money or victuals, confound- 
 ing them with the public feasts in the prytaneum. If by the 
 fees of justice, according to the Roman custom, we understand 
 the payment received directly by the judges, the prytaneia 
 cannot be called fees; but although not the same in name they 
 were so in substance, and the only difference was that they 
 were paid into the public coff"ers, as is the case at present in 
 some places, and the state then paid the judges with this 
 money. For this reason Aristophanes^'^ reckons the prytaneia 
 among the public revenues, which is also the account given by 
 
 2>3 Xenoph. de Rep. Atli. i. 16, Pol- 
 lux viii. 38, Suidas and Photius in v. 
 Trpvrai/eia, where by the 6000 the judges 
 are meant. 
 
 '^^ Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 1139, 
 Suidas in v. npvTavelop, glosses quoted 
 
 by Kiihn ad PoEuc. viii. 38, Casaub. 
 ad Athen. vi. p. 237 F. referring to 
 Aristoph. Nub. 1200, Spanheim ad 
 Nub. 1 182. 
 
 ^'* De Emend. Temp. 
 
 ""^ See above, note 4.
 
 360 
 
 FEES UrON LEGAL PROCEEDINGS. 
 
 [l5K. 
 
 II. 
 
 Suidas and Photius*'^: the presidents of the courts of justice 
 assigned them to the proper authority, which was doubtless 
 the office of the colacretee. For the colacretae had the duty of 
 managing the feasts in the prytaneum, for which, as their name 
 sufficiently proves, the prytaneia were originally assigned, at a 
 time when law-suits were received and introduced in the pry- 
 taneum^'^; the same officers also distributed the wages of the 
 dicasts, after their introduction as a regular stipend, and the 
 prvtaneia were then naturally appointed for the immediate pay- 
 ment of this salar}^ But how great must have been the num- 
 ber of law-suits in order to defray the wages of the dicasts, 
 amounting to about 150 talents! Xenophon gives us to under- 
 stand, that it chiefly was the law-suits of the allies which made 
 it possible to pay the dicasts out of the prytaneia; at the same 
 time, as has been above remarked, additional money must 
 have been supplied from other sources ; for it is not credible 
 that the prytaneia were ever alone sufficient; and, moreover, 
 the pay of the dicasts was only one of those democratic 
 forms, under which the public money was to be divided among 
 the people. 
 
 Chapter X. 
 Fees ujjoii Appeals, The Paracatabole and the Epobelia. 
 
 Another description of the payments made in the courts of 
 justice was the fee {irapd/SoXovy^^ upon appeals (et^eVets'), con- 
 cerning which nothing is known accurately. The paracatabole 
 was, however, a fee of nearly the same nature: this was a joay- 
 ment which was made by any person who either claimed 
 
 *^ UpyTavela : rrpoaodos els to 
 dTjpocriov KUTaraa-aopevT]. Cf- Lex. 
 Seg. p. 192, 17. Valesius (ad ^Maus- 
 (sac. ad Ilarpocrat. p. 32G, ed Gronov.) 
 aud Kuster (ad Nub. 1134) liave given 
 a correct general view of the question. 
 
 '"^ Tiiis is the meaning of Suidas in 
 V. npvTuvelov and TrapaKaTa(3oXr], Schol. 
 
 Aristoph. Nub. 1 139. Concerning the 
 colacreta3 see book ii. ch. 6^ and on 
 the pay of the dicasts, book ii. ch. 15. 
 ^'^ This is the term used by Aristo- 
 tle ; by later writers it was called 
 7rapaj36\iov, Pollux viii. G3; see Sal- 
 mas. :M. U. v. p. 198; lludtwalcker 
 von den Diateten, p. 127.
 
 CH. X.] FEES UPON APPEALS. 361 
 
 {dfM(l)tcr^7]T€l) from the state any confiscated property, or from 
 individuals an estate adjudged to him, and it was forfeited if the 
 party lost his suit. The fifth part of the property claimed 
 {tcov d/jL(j)t(T^7]TovfjLii^(ov) was paid before the action as paracata- 
 bole, if the party laid claim to confiscated property; and the 
 tenth part if he claimed an inheritance or property of heir- 
 esses"", and in fact the payment took place at the preliminary 
 investigation into the case {dvdKpLo-i(;Y'^\ The similarity of 
 both cases with the appeal may be seen from this fact, that all 
 confiscations of property were founded upon a judicial verdict, 
 and whoever laid claim to property thus forfeited, if he did not 
 in strictness of speech appeal against the decision, yet appealed 
 against its appUcation to a particular object; the resemblance 
 is also strengthened by the circumstance, that the paracatabole 
 was only paid in cases relating to the inheritance of property, 
 when the plaintifi" sought to obtain possession of an inheritance 
 already adjudged to another person (eTrtSi/tafoyLteva)*", so that 
 in this instance also an appeal was made against a former legal 
 decision. 
 
 In both varieties of the paracatabole the questions arise, by 
 whom was it received, if the party who had deposited it lost the 
 cause, and whether other justice fees and fines could be com- 
 bined with it. In order to determine these problems, it will be 
 necessary to premise the following observations. The pay- 
 ments made in law suits were of three kinds : in the first place, 
 there were mere justice fees, such as prytaneia and parastasis, 
 which the unsuccessful party paid: in the second place, fines 
 
 "' Pollux viii. 39j 32; Harpocrat. ' Didymus says in Harpocration in 
 Suid. Phot, in TTapaKarafdoXrj, Lex. Seg. j TTfJonefMnra' elal yap ol to. TreyuTrra tcov 
 p. 290 (Harpocration refers to Lysias, TiixTjfxdTcov (he should have said rau 
 Hyperides, and other orators): see \ dfji(f)ia0T}Tnvfj.€va>v) TrapaKaTa^dXXeadai 
 Harpocration and Suidas in dfjL(f)ia- j (fiaaiv, as Avaias iv tS Kara 'AttoXXo- 
 ^TjTclv, and concerning the inheritances , da>pov vnoarjfiaivei. All the rest of this 
 see Pollux viii. 32 ; Timseus Lexic. article is worthless, as has been aheady 
 Plat, in TrapaKara^oXr}, and there | remarked by Yalesius in his notes to 
 Ruhnkeu; Demosth. c. Macart. p. ;Maussac. 
 
 1051, 20, 1054, 27 (from a law), c. ; "' Isaeus de Hagn. Hered. p. 2. 
 Leochar. p. 1090, ext. p. 1092, 20. ! ^^^ See Buusen de Jure Hcrcdit. 
 Isicus mentions it in several places, i Atheu. 1, 2, 3. 
 And to this probably belongs what |
 
 362 
 
 FEES UPON APPEALS. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 {Tt/jbr]/jLaTa), which the successful plaintiff received in private, 
 and the state in public suits, excepting that in a phasis, the 
 injured party received the fine, and in certain private suits, a 
 fine was annexed to be paid to the state: and, lastly, certain 
 compensations, which in particular law suits, the unsuccessful 
 was compelled to make to the successful party, for the risk to 
 which he had exposed him, for example the epobeUa. Now 
 the paracatabole appears to be of the latter kind, and it was 
 evidently introduced in order to protect the state and all legal 
 heirs from the vexatious suits of self-interested plaintiffs: from 
 this it follows that it must have been received by the party who 
 was injured by the suit, viz. in claims for confiscated property 
 by the state, in cases of inheritance by the heirs. From this 
 view of the case, the litigants were probably in addition to the 
 paracatabole compelled to pay the common justice fees, since 
 they would have paid them if there had been no paracatabole, 
 according to the respective circumstances of the suit, although 
 I have not been able to find any information upon this point. 
 The unsuccessful plaintiff does not appear to have been subject 
 to any other punishments or augmentations of punishment 
 {TrpocTTLfjLrjfjLaTa). It should also be observed, that the payment 
 of the paracatabole could only have been required from the 
 complaining party, as a punishment for vexatious litigation. 
 
 Something must also be said on the subject of the epobelia 
 {67rci)/3e\ia), since in the writings of both early and modern 
 scholars as little clear and definite information is found upon 
 this point as upon the other justice fees and fines'". The 
 epobelia is the sixth part of the assessment of the suit {ri/jLTj/jia), 
 and was so called because an obolus was paid for every drachma 
 of the valuation. As this circumstance is manifest from the 
 name alone, and the best grammarians give the same account"*; 
 and as the examples of the epobelia occurring in Demosthenes, 
 
 ^'^^ Even the accurate Heraldus 
 (Animadv. in Salmas. Observ. iii. 4, 
 8 — 11, 5 ad fin ) has adopted an en- 
 tirely false view of the question, and 
 Hudtwalcker only incidentally touches 
 upon this subject in a few places. 
 
 ^" Harpocrat. Etymol. Suid. Zona- 
 ras in eVco/SeX/a, Lex. Seg. p. 255; 
 Schol. Plat. Ruhnk. p. 239; Pollux 
 viii. 30, 48. ix. GO ; cf. Salmas. II. U. 
 p. 12 sqq.
 
 CH. X.] FEES UPON APPEALS. 363 
 
 which will be adduced presently, prove it beyond a doubt, the 
 statement which Hesychius and Eustathius have derived from 
 ignorant writers*", that the epobelia was the tenth part of the 
 assessment, does not require refutation; it owes its origin to a 
 confusion with the paracatabole, not unlike that which we have 
 already seen in the case of the prytaneia. The true nature of 
 this fine is given in general terms by Harpocration, who states 
 that it was an additional valuation (^Trpoarlfxrjfjua) fixed by law, 
 independent of the decision of the judges"^: this account, how- 
 ever, leaves the questions open, in what law suits, by whom, 
 under what circumstances, connected with what, and to whom, 
 was it paid. 
 
 According to the Etymologist^*^, the epobelia was introduced 
 because many persons had been vexatiously accused in causes 
 relating to money, particularly with regard to bottomry or 
 sea security: on which account the law imposed the epobelia 
 upon the plaintiff, for the prevention of vexatious accusations 
 {avKocfyayTLo) ; and afterwards it was applied equally to all other 
 pecuniary causes (^^pT^/xart/cal hUai). Probably this alludes to 
 the fact mentioned by Isocrates against Callimachus^*^, who 
 states that Archinus, after the government of the thirty tyrants, 
 introduced the payment of the epobelia in law suits in which 
 the defendant was allowed the right of instituting a paragraphe 
 against the plaintiff, in order to protect him from vexatious 
 accusations. The case mentioned in the speech of Demosthenes 
 against Stephanus for false testimony*^% is precisely of this 
 nature. The orator's client, Apollodorus, had brought an action 
 against his step-father Phormion to recover a sum of money 
 which he claimed from him; Phormion, on the other hand, 
 instituted a paragraphe, and Apollodorus, having been unsuc- 
 cessful in the suit, was condemned to pay the epobelia. But 
 the litigants were also exposed to the risk of the epobelia in 
 pecuniary cases, even when there was no paragraphe, as may be 
 
 '^* Hesych. in eVca^eXt'a ; Eustath. i is transcribed, 
 ad Odyss. A. p. 1405, 27. ' ''^'^^ In the beginning ; comp. below, 
 
 ^^ Barpocrat. in npoa-TiixrjixaTu, and i chap. 15, 16. 
 thence Photius. ^^^ P. 1103, 15. 
 
 "^7 From which Suidas in eTrco/ScXia '
 
 364 FEES UPON APPEALS. [bK. III. 
 
 seen from the law suit of Demosthenes against his guardians^ 
 and the cause against Dionysodorus on account of the non-re- 
 payment of a loan of money: and also in a phasis which related 
 to a fine; in this instance, however, it was doubtless limited by 
 certain conditions, which will be more aptly pointed out in 
 another place: and, finally, in the cross action^^° {dvTLypacjir]), 
 on account of the appearance of A-exation which it bore. It 
 cannot be proved that any epobelia was required in actions for 
 an assaxilt. The private suit for the same offence {SUrj alKia^) 
 of necessity indeed led to nothing more than a fine, but it was 
 distinguished in several essential points from a common pecu- 
 niary law suit; and the only known case in which epobelia was 
 paid in a private action for an assault, related in the speech 
 against Euergus and Mnesibulus, had also the nature of a cross 
 suit, which circumstance introduced the obligation of the epo- 
 belia. In the public action for an assault [hiKT) vjSpecos) it is 
 impossible to conceive that any epobelia existed; nor when 
 ^schines against Timarchus^^^ supposes the case of a person 
 bringing an action against a youth, who, having sold his chastity 
 by a written document, had violated his engagement, and con- 
 siders it to be just that the plaintiff should both lose his suit, 
 and sufi'er the penalty of death, " not only paying the epobelia, 
 but also a fine for the other injury ,^^ must it be supposed that 
 the plaintifi* generally paid the epobelia in public actions for 
 bodily wrong; for this would not be a suit of this nature, but 
 an action connected with pecuniary matters, which, as the 
 agreement was contrary to law, would necessarily be lost; con- 
 sidered in the light of a pecuniary case, the plaintiff would of 
 course sufifer the penalty of the epobelia ; but the orator sup- 
 poses him to be punished with far greater severity for the 
 seduction and disgrace of an Athenian youth. Speaking gene- 
 rally, the epobelia only applied in cases relating to money, and 
 not in public actions, except in the phasis. 
 
 •230 Pollux viii. 58. I (tlv ck tov biKactr-qpiov ov rrjv eirio^eXiav 
 
 •231 "Where the chief words that refer I fiovov uXka koI aXXj/y v^piv: the case 
 
 to this subject are, eneira ou KuraXeva- \ Jiere supposed is iralprjaLs kutu avvSrj- 
 
 6i](j€TaL 6 piadovixevos tup ^Adr^vtilov , Kas, which actually occurred. See 
 
 napa tovs vupuvs Koi Trpoo-ocpXcoi/ anei- \ Lysias c. biuiou. p. 1 17, 14^.
 
 CH. X.] 
 
 FEES UPON APPEALS. 
 
 365 
 
 With regard to the party who was bound to pay the epobelia 
 there may seem to exist some doubt, for the passages of the 
 grammarians apparently contradict one another, and the ancients 
 do not explain themselves with sufficient distinctness. It seems 
 to me probable, that not the plaintiflf only, but the unsuccessful 
 party in general, was subject to this payment, although a deci- 
 sive proof to this effect cannot now be obtained. By the law 
 of Archinus, both parties in the litigation, as well the accuser as 
 the party instituting a paragraphe, in case he was condemned, 
 was bound to pay the epobelia^^^; which however cannot be 
 accounted for by the reason which Pollux mentions*^% that the 
 paragraphe was similar to a cross suit, and therefore both parties 
 were considered as plaintiffs: Pollux asserts, that in the phasis 
 the unsuccessful party paid the epobelia, without making any 
 distinction between plaintiff and defendant; which he also states 
 in the most general terms of the epobelia^^*. And doubtless if 
 in a phasis the defendant paid the epobelia equally with the 
 plaintiff, in case he lost the suit, by the same reason he must 
 have paid it in a money case to which the epobelia applied, 
 even if it was only a private cause, for in the phasis the epobelia 
 was only added in reference to the money which the injured 
 party endeavoured to obtain from the defendant ; that is to say, 
 merely in reference to that which in the phasis is a private 
 concern; and if the plaintiff was exposed to the danger of the 
 epobelia, it was but just that the hazard of the accuser should 
 be increased in an equal proportion. 
 
 We have two instances of the plaintiff paying the epobeha 
 in private cases; but if correctly understood, they do not war- 
 
 '"- See above, chap. 9. 
 
 223 Pollux viii. 58, upon the principle 
 of Reus eacipiendo fit actor. 
 
 '^* viii. 48 and 39. In the former 
 chapter he says, 6 5e /xj) ixeraXa^cov to 
 7re/x7rrov ^epos roiv ylrrjCJiuiv ttjv eTTco^e- 
 Xiav 7rpoaa)(j)\i(TKav€, where by the 
 word TTpoo-ocfAtaKavciv the grammarian 
 means to express the additional loss 
 besides the loss of the suit : in the 
 same manner in viii, 58, o 8e avnypa- 
 
 yj/dfxevos fxr) Kparrjaas rrjv inoi^cklav 
 7rpocrco(fiXi(TKav€. Demosth, c. Stephan. 
 ■^evbop.. i. p. 1103, 15, TrpoaocpiXcov 8e 
 rrjv eVco/SeXiai/j and yEschin. ut sup. I 
 mention this, that it might not be 
 thought that by Trpoo-ocfAtaKaueiv a pre- 
 ^^ous fine is implied. In the other 
 passage (c. 39) Pollux says, encolSeXta 
 8' rjv TO eKTOV [xepos tov Tip.T]^aTOSf o 
 a>cf:€i\ev 6 alpedets.
 
 366 FEES UPON APPEALS. [bK. III. 
 
 rant us in inferring that the defendant, if he was unsuccessful, 
 would not have been compelled to pay it. Darius and Pamphi- 
 lus lent Dionysodorus 300 drachmas upon bottomr)^; this latter 
 person acted contrary to the agreement and the commercial 
 laws: "but, notwithstanding all this,^^ says the orator, "he dared 
 to come into court, with the intent of depriving me of the epo- 
 belia, and of carrying it off to his own house, in addition to the 
 other money of which he has defrauded me^^\" The silence of 
 the orator cannot be considered as a proof that the defendant, 
 in case he was unsuccessful, did not pay the epobelia. Demos- 
 thenes says in the first speech against Aphobus^^®, that if he 
 was unsuccessful, he should have to pay the epobelia without 
 being assessed {ari/jLijTos) ; if Aphobus lost, he should not have 
 to pay the fine until the assessment of the judges had been 
 made {tl/jltjto^). This expression does not by any means 
 exclude the possibility of Aphobus being compelled to pay the 
 epobelia. Demosthenes had estimated his damages against 
 Aphobus at 600 minas: " If I lose my cause," he says, " I shall 
 be forced to pay 100 minas for epobelia, without being assessed;'' 
 for as he had himself estimated the damages, the estimate 
 remained, and the epobelia was thus immediately determined, 
 that being the only manner in which it could be fixed. If, on 
 the other hand, Aphobus lost, he was empowered to put in a 
 petition that the judges would moderate the damages, and com- 
 pel the plaintiff to lower his demands : the fine was then assessed, 
 and consequently the epobelia also, which followed the assess- 
 ment of the damages. Demosthenes, however, had no reason 
 for laying any stress upon the latter point, as the payment of 
 the epobelia is naturally understood. In a third case, viz. the 
 cross action in the speech against Euergus and Mnesibulus, no 
 distinction can be made between the plaintiff and defendant, as 
 both of them come forward in a double character. Now al- 
 though the grammarians*" (whose joint testimony has only the 
 authority of a single witness) state that the plaintiff paid the 
 epobelia to the defendant, if he lost the suit, they do not actu- 
 
 ^^ Demosth. c. Dionysod. p. 1284,2. 1 "" Ilarpocrat. Etyraol. Suid. Scliol. 
 *36 p. 834, 25. I Platon. Lex. Seg.
 
 CH. X.] FEES UPON APPEALS. 36j 
 
 ally deny that the defendant was also obliged to pay it : but as 
 it was originally introduced for the prevention of vexatious 
 accusations, they only mention the plaintiff, and state that, in 
 case he lost, he was forced to pay the epobelia to the defendant, 
 as compensation for the risk which he had occasioned. It should 
 also be observed, that the unsuccessful party was only com- 
 pelled to pay the epobelia in case he did not obtain the fifth part 
 of the votes^"^, and therefore his guilt might be considered as 
 sufficiently manifest. 
 
 Our next question is, whether the epobelia could be con- 
 nected with other justice fees and fines ? It had not the nature 
 of a sacramentum, nor was it deposited before the verdict, but 
 was paid immediately after the loss of the cause, as is evident 
 from the speech of Demosthenes against Euergus and Mnesibu- 
 lus"°; from the law suit against Aphobus; and even from Iso- 
 crates against Callimachus: consequently, some sacramentum 
 must necessarily have been paid for the introduction of the suit; 
 and accordingly we know for certain that in the first of the three 
 cases above quoted the unsuccessful party paid the prytaneia 
 and the epobelia, and that prytaneia were also paid in the last 
 case^'"'. Again, the loss of a fine {rifJLTjfjba) was sometimes con- 
 nected with the payment of the epobelia: this loss, however, 
 could necessarily be suffered only by the defendant, and by him 
 in every case in which he was unsuccessful; if he did not obtain 
 the fifth part of the votes, the payment of the epobelia was 
 appended to the fine, according to the amount of a sixth part of 
 the money which he was condemned to pay: the plaintiff, on 
 the other hand, was not subject to any fine, but only paid the 
 epobelia upon the sum which he had assessed against the de- 
 fendant, in case he did not obtain the fifth part of the votes; 
 unless by the institution of a cross action he had taken the 
 double character of plaintiff and defendant. All these particu- 
 lars might have been assumed a priori, even apart from the 
 authority of law suits now extant; it is manifest therefore that 
 the statement of Hesychius, made upon the authority of Didy- 
 mus, that the epobelia was a fine which followed the assessment 
 
 238 Isocrat. in Callimach. 5, Pollux viii. 48. ^^^ Comp. chap. 9. '^'^ Vid. ibid.
 
 368 FEES UPON APPEALS. [bK. III. 
 
 of the lost cause" ^, merely refers to the determination of the 
 epobelia according to the assessment of the suit : for this pay- 
 ment in reference to the plaintiff was regulated by the assess- 
 ment which he made against the defendant;, and in reference to 
 the defendant by the assessment appointed by the court: on 
 the other hand, we should misconceive the meaning of the 
 grammarian, if we supposed that the epobelia was so far a con- 
 sequence of the assessment or fine, that it was only paid in cases 
 in which the fine itself or the timema was paid. For in all 
 cases mentioned above, in which the plaintiffs speak of their 
 being exposed to the risk of losing the epobelia, there is no 
 trace of any apprehension of a fine. 
 
 Lastly, a peculiar circumstance occurred in the phasis, as 
 being a public suit. In this form of proceeding it must be 
 inferred, from the circumstances of the case, that the defendant, 
 if he lost the cause, paid the fine, and also the epobelia, if he 
 did not obtain the fifth part of the votes : the plaintiff indeed 
 had no reason to apprehend the first payment, but if he 
 was unsuccessful in his suit, he was in the same case com- 
 pelled to pay the epobelia; and if he did not obtain the 
 fifth part of the votes, i. e, in the very case in which he was 
 subject to the epobelia, he was forced to pay to the state the 
 usual fine of 1000 drachmas'^"-; the former regulation arising 
 from the nature of the money suit {xpVH'^Ti''<:v ^^kt)), the latter 
 from its being a public cause. Are we however to suppose that 
 both these payments were required in every phasis, according 
 to the hypothesis which we have just made ? This point cannot 
 be determined without taking a more accurate view of the nature 
 of the phasis. 
 
 The phasis then was sometimes a purely public suit, as for 
 example in the case of plunder of monies, or unsold mines 
 
 ^*^ *Ak6\ov6oPT(0 TJJS KaTClbtKTJS TlfJLT]- 
 
 fiari o(p\r]fia: an inaccurate expres- 
 sion which cannot be applied to the 
 plaintiff, unless, with all probability 
 against us, we prefer writing Biktjs 
 with Salmasius M. U. p. 14 (who be- 
 sides tills has rightly corrected the 
 
 passage as I have given it), and Palmer 
 upon Ilesychius. I pass over the mass 
 of confusion which is contained in the 
 notes of the other commentators upon 
 this passage of Ilesychius. 
 
 ^'=^ Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1323, 19.
 
 CH. X.] FEKS UPON APPEALS. 369 
 
 belonging to the state, actions by which no private individual 
 was injured; at other times, it was a suit partly public and 
 partly private, for instance, if an action was instituted for the 
 embezzlement of orphans^ property : it could not in any case be 
 solely a private suit, for it would thus have lost the distinctive 
 character of the phasis, and have become a mere money suit for 
 compensation of the injury suffered. Now, when the phasis 
 was a purely public suit, its only object was a fine to be paid to 
 state ; and in this case neither the plaintiff nor the defendant 
 could ever have paid the epobelia, since this payment was only 
 required in cases which took the form of a private money suit, 
 as its origin alone shows, the intent of it being to repress frivo- 
 lous accusations, or on the part of the defendant to prevent him 
 from vexatiously withholding the property of another person. 
 Hence in the purely public phasis, the only penalty was doubt- 
 less that of 1000 drachmas, which fine is in the speech against 
 Theocrines quoted from a law, in reference to this point, without 
 any mention of the epobelia in a phasis, as the penalty of the 
 unsuccessful plaintiflf, if he did not obtain the fifth part of the 
 votes ; whether the plaintiff had made the assessment for a fine 
 or some other punishment. If however the phasis was of a 
 mixed nature, the object of the accuser was to obtain a fine for 
 the compensation of the injured individual, and a fine to the 
 state as a penalty for the injury done to it: in this case probably 
 the epobelia applied both to the plaintiff and defendant in 
 reference to the first view of the suit, and the penalty of 1000 
 drachmas on the part of the plaintiff, in reference to the public 
 nature of the action. Lastly, if the injured person brought on 
 a case, which would have justified a phasis, merely as a private 
 suit, the epobelia alone applied. From this then it may be 
 also determined to whom the epobelia was paid. The gram- 
 marians**^ say that the defendant received it from the plaintiff, ' 
 if he (the defendant) gained the cause ; from which it is evident, 
 that if the plaintiff was successful he received it from the 
 defendant ; supposing always that both parties were bound to 
 
 ^*^ Etyinol. Siiid. Scliul. Plat. Lex. I yoiv napa tov diotKovTos, f2 ti)u diKtjv 
 
 2 B
 
 370 FEES UPON APPEALS. [bK. III. 
 
 pay it, as we have assumed. And that in private suits the epo- 
 belia was received by the successful party and not by the state, 
 is completely proved by the orations which are still extant***. 
 But, it will be asked, to whom did the epobelia in the case of 
 the phasis belong ? If the phasis was a purely public action, 
 the epobeUa did not apply; where it did exist, it was merely 
 annexed in so far that the phasis contained, as it were, an 
 action for compensation claimed by a private individual, in order 
 to restrain vexatious suits, or the withholding of property 
 belonging to the plaintiff. If then the plaintiff was unsuccess- 
 ful, the epobelia was paid to the defendant, in the same manner 
 as in a private money-suit; but if the plaintiff was successful, 
 either the party whose rights had been violated by the defend- 
 ant, and who was represented by the public accuser, received 
 the epobelia in the same manner that the injured party received 
 the fine (for the circumstance of the plaintiff being a third 
 person might appear quite accidental in reference to the money- 
 suit contained in the phasis), or it was paid to the plaintiff as 
 compensation for the risk to which he himself had been exposed. 
 The state therefore could not in any case have had any share in 
 the epobelia. 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 The Fines accruing to the State. 
 
 The public income arising from judicial cases was further 
 increased by the fines for illegal acts, as far as they were esti- 
 mated in money and paid to the state. 
 
 All fines were called valuations or assessments {TifjbrjfiaTa), a 
 term which comprehended damages and all punishments esti- 
 mated in money, because they were determined by the valuing 
 or TLfi7}cn9, and by the abuse of the word it came to signify the 
 punishment itself. 
 
 In treating of this matter I shall chiefly follow the guidance 
 of Heraldus, who has entered into a comprehensive examination 
 
 Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. p. 1158, Demosth. c. Dionysod. p. 1284,2.
 
 CH. XI.] FIXES ACCRUING TO THE STATE. S'jl 
 
 of it; but agreeably to my purpose I shall limit my inquiries to 
 what is either requisite for the comprehension of the whole 
 question, or is immediately connected with the public revenue; 
 for which reason I shall set aside all assessments which were 
 not made in money, and in great measure also the question of 
 damages, as alien to my subject. 
 
 All punishments (fines included) were either defined by law 
 as affecting both pubhc and private actions, or were with respect 
 to some public actions left to the discretion of the judges, which 
 was however limited in particular cases; certain punishments 
 being defined^ from which they were to select that which 
 appeared to them best adapted to the case*'\ An action in 
 which the punishment was a fine or other penalty affixed by 
 law, was called an unassessed suit, from the laws having defined 
 no certain penalty [a'ycbv arlfir^ros) ; if it was necessary to assess 
 it for the occasion, it was called an assessed suit {tl/jl7)t6(;Y*'^, 
 In all private causes, the fines were with a single exception 
 fixed by law'*^^, and if not absolutely, they were fixed propor- 
 tionably to the value in litigation. Thus in the action for 
 injury {BiKrj ^Xd^rjs) in many cases a scale fixed according to 
 proportions was the only one which could be adopted, as the 
 amount was to be determined by the injury done, which 
 required to be accurately known in order to admit of an assess- 
 ment. In this case it was ruled by the law, that if the injury 
 had been done unintentionally the single, and if intentionally 
 the double, assessment should be restored""^. The law, on the 
 other hand, fixed all penalties absolutely which had not the 
 character of compensation, as, for example, in a case of slan- 
 derous words [KaKTjyopia), at 500 drachmas'^*^, and in the action 
 for non-appearance of a witness {Slktj XeiTTo/Maprvpiov) at 1000 
 drachmas"". 
 
 *** Herald. Anim. in Salmas. Obs. 
 ad I. A. et R. iii. 1, 2. 
 
 "•» Herald, iii. 2, Mattliiae Miscell. 
 Philog. vol. i. p. 276, 277- 
 
 '■^*' Ulpian. ad Demosth. c. Mid. 
 p. 325. 
 
 *^8 Demosth. c. Mid, p. 528. 
 
 ^^ Isocrat. c. Lochit. 4, Lysias c* 
 Theomnest. p. 354. See Matthia? ut 
 sup. Hudtwalcker von den Diiiteten, 
 p. 149 sqq. 
 
 250 Pollux viii. 37. Compare Har- 
 pocration, Photius, and Suidas in v. 
 KkT]Trjp€s, Lex. Seg. p. 272, 10. 
 
 2 B 2
 
 372 
 
 FINES ACCRUING TO THE STATE. 
 
 [bk. Ill 
 
 The only case in which the fine was undetermined was the 
 private action for assault {Bikt) aUias), in which the procedure 
 upon the whole resembled that in public causes, and it was 
 thus an assessed action"^, in order that the court and the 
 plaintiff might be able to estimate the fine according to the 
 degree of injury received: it could, however, be only rated in 
 money*'**. But in all private suits the plaintiff received the 
 assessment, so that we have no farther concern with this species 
 of cases. In public suits, on the contrary, the state received 
 the fine of the defendant, unless the money-cases of private 
 individuals were implicated in them, e. g, in the phasis concern- 
 ing cases of misconduct of guardians or violation of commercial 
 law, in which the assessment accrued to the injured party, if 
 the plaintiff succeeded; in all other public causes, however, the 
 penalties of infamy, death, &c. might be appointed in place of 
 fines. Now these public causes were either assessed or unas- 
 sessed: in the first case, the plaintiff generally assessed the 
 injury in his plaint (rt/^a, irpoTLfia)^ the defendant made a 
 counter-assessment {avTircfjua, vTroTUfia) ; the court then decided 
 upon the assessment {niMa, eiriKpiveL), agreeing with one or the 
 other. At the same time the plaintiff might give up his own 
 higher assessment and accede to that of the defendant; and in 
 like manner the judges might depart from their own assessment 
 and take that of the defendant, if the plaintiff consented. 
 
 This method of proceeding {avyxcoprja-aLy^^ was much used 
 in public actions in which there was no punishment distinctly 
 fixed for the defendant, but only for the plaintiff, in case of his 
 being unsuccessful; thence in the writing of accusation it was 
 always necessary to fix some assessment; there were, however, 
 cases in actions of this kind, in which the law only left the 
 plaintiff the choice between certain fixed punishments; thus 
 e.ff. in the action for bribery {<ypa(l)r) ScopoBoKias) it was neces- 
 sary either to fix as a punishment death or the tenth part of the 
 
 ^** Harpocrat. in v. alKtas, and the 
 authorities cited by Matthise, p. 272, 
 273. 
 
 *'^ Lysias ap. EtjTnol. et Suid. in v. 
 
 25' Herald, iii. 1, 10. Instead of 
 TijiaVf vTrorifiaVy &c., rifxaa-Oai, vTTori- 
 fiao-Oai, are also used without any 
 alteration in the meanino;.
 
 CH. XI.] 
 
 FINES ACCRUING TO THE STATE. 
 
 373 
 
 sum received^^^ In a phasis an assessment was necessary by 
 reason of the damages to be paid, and we also kno^v from dis- 
 tinct authority that such was the case^^^; in other public causes^ 
 however, there was no assessment, the penalty having been 
 already appointed by law, which was the case in an information 
 
 Lastly, the additional assessment [Trpoarlfiyfia), which was 
 added as an enhancement of the punishment, must be separated 
 from the simple assessment. This was a fine, which the court 
 had full power to impose in certain cases in which it was per- 
 mitted by laws or decrees of the people, or which regularly fol- 
 lowed under particular circumstances, as the epobelia. The 
 additional assessment was in some cases fixed by law; thus in 
 instances of theft, which were not capital crimes, the additional 
 punishment was fixed at five days and nights^ imprisonment; it 
 rested however with the judgment of the court whether they 
 would add or omit it^^^ 
 
 To what degree private suits admitted of an assessment has 
 been already explained, i. e. only in damages, and likewise in 
 the private suit for assault; of the former kind are the action 
 for injury {^Xd^rjs) and the action against guardians, when 
 brought on as a private suit [Blkt] iTrcrpoTrrj^; or iir lt poire La<;), 
 and the like. In these the plaintiff made an assessment in his 
 plaint which referred solely to his own injury, without there 
 being any counter-assessment on the part of the defendant. 
 The latter was, however, at liberty to put in a petition, and the 
 judges had the power of diminishing the assessment'". Heral- 
 dus"° has justly considered as a compensation of this kind the 
 assessment of 1 talent, which occurs in the speech of Demos- 
 thenes against Stephanus in the private action for false testi- 
 mony {Blkv yjrevSofjiapTvpiov). But in all causes for damages 
 
 25-* Herald, iii. 3, 1. 
 
 2" Pollux viii. 47. 
 
 256 Herald, iii. 2, 9—14. The chief 
 passage in the law of Solon is given by 
 Deraosth. c. Tiinocrat. p. 733 (comp. 
 the explanation, p. 746, 12); from 
 which fXT] should be struck out in Ly- 
 sias c. Theomnest. p. 357, 0, and not 
 changed into ftcV with Ileraldus and 
 
 Taylor. There are indeed in this 
 passage other difficulties, which I now 
 intentionally pass by, as they could 
 only be removed by a detailed exami- 
 nation. 
 
 257 Herald, iii. 4. 
 
 258 iii. 1, 14. The passage of De- 
 mosthenes is p. 1115, 25.
 
 374 
 
 FINES ACCRUING TO THE STATE. 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 the assessment was not left to the litigant, as in several cases of 
 this description a certain fine was already determined by law"^ 
 With regard to the other case, i. e. for assault, it is of so 
 remarkable a character, and we have been already so often com- 
 pelled to mention it, that it cannot be properly neglected in this 
 place. In this case two kinds of action might be instituted, as 
 in the Roman law, differing however not in respect to the object, 
 but only in the form and the consequences, viz. the public 
 [SiKT] vppecds) and the private suit [hUrj alKias) ; because by an 
 assault committed upon any person, either the state might be 
 considered as wronged (it being thought that the state and the 
 public freedom were injured by any act of violence, even if a 
 slave was assaulted), or only the individual, according to the 
 views and inclination of the plaintiff"". If the plaintiff brought 
 it on as a private cause, the defendant could only be condemned 
 to pay a fine, which the plaintiff received, who in this case was 
 
 ^" Herald, iii. 5. 
 
 **** It is however remarkable that 
 the ypa(f)T) v^pcas is sometimes repre- 
 sented to be a private suit, because^ 
 like many other public actions, it only 
 referred indirectly to an injury done 
 to the state, and immediately to the 
 injury of an individual. In this sense 
 Demosthenes or rather Meidias (adv. 
 iMid. p. 522, extr.) may call the 
 BiKTj v^pfcos an Ibia diKrjy in opposition 
 to the npo^oXr) before the people, 
 which must be considered as an action 
 for a direct injury done to the state, 
 for example, by the disturbance of a 
 festival, or an injury done to sacred 
 persons or property, and to public 
 offices (cf. p. 424, 42')); the irpo^oXrj 
 being the method of proceeding against 
 such as had shown themselves dis- 
 affected to the state, or had cheated 
 the public, and therefore it might be 
 instituted against sycophants, or against 
 persons who had injured tlie silver 
 mines still belonging to the state, or 
 for emliezzlement of the public money. 
 (See Taylor ad Demosth. c. Mid.' p. 
 ^62 sqq. Reisk. Append. Crit. vol. i. 
 
 Matthise Miscell. Philog. voL i. p. 238.) 
 The meaning of the orator is most 
 evident when he says (p. 524, 21,) that 
 whoever injures a private individual 
 in deeds or in words, may be prose- 
 cuted by the ypa<i>rj v^pecos Koi diKj] 
 KaKijyopUis, and that if tlie same is 
 done to a thesmothetes, the guilty 
 party will be arifios for the single 
 offence. In this passage too the 
 ypa<Pr] v^pecof is considei"ed as Idla, as 
 the word Idiau Avhich has been added 
 from the ISISS. also refers to ypa(f)rjv. 
 The orator therefore does not in this 
 more than in other orations deny that 
 the action for v^pis was a public action 
 (ypa(Prj), although he calls it Idia, cf. 
 p. 623, 18, p. 524, 21, p. 528 extr. 
 From this fact moreover, viz. that the 
 ypacf)rj vftpews might ralate to the in- 
 jury done to a private individual, and 
 in fact was usually so considered, it 
 may be seen why Dionysius Ilalicar- 
 nassensis in the life of Dinarchus enu- 
 merates the speech of this orator 
 against Proxenus {dnoXoyia O/Specos) 
 among the private speeches. The 
 ypn(pr) ]v(3p(a)s idla occurs in another
 
 CH. XI.] 
 
 FINES ACCRUING TO THE STATE. 
 
 375 
 
 necessarily the injured party; if, however, the cause was brought 
 on as a public suit before the thesmothetee^*', (which might be 
 done by a party having no interest in the event of it,) the state 
 received the whole fine*^^, although the punishment might be 
 capitaP^^. Consequently in the public proceeding there was no 
 private advantage for the plaintiff; whereas in addition to the 
 loss of the suit he was also subject to the risk of forfeiting 
 1000 drachmas, if he had not a fifth part of the votes on his 
 side, and therefore nothing but excessive hatred or disinterest- 
 edness could excite any man to institute a public action for an 
 assault. In both forms of action, however, an assessment was 
 made on the part of the plaintiff, the course of proceeding in 
 the private action for assault being similar in several points to 
 that in public suits : on the other hand, in the private action 
 for assault there appears to have been this deviation from the 
 procedure in public cases, that the defendant was not permitted 
 to make any counter-assessment, but the court followed either 
 its own or the plaintiff^s assessments^*. 
 
 Chapter XII. 
 
 Examples of Fines, 
 
 In order to enable the reader to judge as to the amount of 
 the income which the state of Athens derived from fines, it will 
 be advisable to cite some examples of them: others will be 
 omitted, as a complete enumeration would be equally tedious 
 and unavailing. 
 
 As it vAW be necessary to speak partly of fines appointed to 
 be paid into the public coffers, and partly into those of temples, 
 we may previously remark, that in the laws of Solon, the pre- 
 cious metals being at that time high in price, fines were fixed at 
 very low rates^®^; e,g, whoever defrauded another person in 
 
 sense in the law in Demosth. adv. 
 Mid. p. 529, 23, concerning which it 
 is sufficient to refer to Heraldus ii. 
 10, 12. 
 
 '^^ Matthiae, vol. i. p. 247, 249. 
 
 ■^^^ Besides Heraldus see more par- 
 
 ticularly Demosth. c. Mid. p. 528, 27, 
 Poll. viii. 42. 
 
 2«^ Lysias ap. Etymol. et Suid. in v. 
 v^pis. See Petit vi. 5, 4. 
 
 264 Herald, iii. 3, 15-17. 
 
 ••^" Plutarch. Solon. 23.
 
 376 EXAMPLES OF FIXES. [l5K. 111. 
 
 public or ceremonial affairs, paid 3 drachmas to the injured 
 party, and 2 to the state, whereas in later times the penalty for 
 libellous words was 500 drachmas; in like manner the fines in 
 the Twelve Tables were, as is well known, very inconsiderable. 
 To these ancient times must be referred the law which ordered 
 that any person who occupied any land within the Pelasgicum 
 should pay 3 drachmas''^^ And judged according to the stan- 
 dard of later times, the fine of 100 drachmas, which the archon 
 had to pay according to Solon's regulation, if he did not lay a 
 curse upon exportation, was of small amount*". 
 
 Of later times, however, it may on the contrar)^ be asserted, 
 that the fines were fixed at very high rates. If the prytanes 
 did not hold certain assemblies according to rule, or the proedri 
 did not propose the appointed business, each prytaneus had to 
 pay 1000 and each proedrus 40 drachmas to Minerva*^^; and 
 for conviction nothing more than an information (evSec^Ls) was 
 necessary. If the officers appointed to superintend the weights 
 and measures performed their duties negligently, they paid, 
 according to a later decree, a penalty of 1000 drachmas to 
 Ceres and Proserpine*®^ Whoever declared falsely that a 
 citizen's property belonged to the state, paid a forfeit of 1000 
 drachmas for his act of sycophancy*^". If the demarch did not 
 perform his duty with regard to the interment of a dead body 
 found in the demus, he forfeited 1000 drachmas to the state"'. 
 If an orator conducted himself indecorously in the senate or the 
 public assembly, he could be fined 50 drachmas for each offence, 
 which might be raised to a higher sum at the pleasure of the 
 people^^^ This fine was collected by the practores for the 
 public. A citizen who cohabited with an alien, paid a penalty. 
 
 ^^® Pollux viii. 101. ^''^ Siiidas in v. dfj.(f)iopKia, Orat. c. 
 
 2^7 Plutarcli. Solon. 24. Nicostrat. ap Demosth. p. 1246, 9. 
 
 268 pg^j^ -^ j^ ^ rpjjjg penalty was imposed in a diiaj 
 
 *^^ Corp. Inscript. No. 104. Large dnoypacprjs, as in the case of non-suc- 
 fincs, as e. g. of 1000 drachmas, were cess in other public actions (p. 407). 
 paid to Juno (Demosth. c. Macart. p. Cf. Harpocrat. in. v. d7roypa(j>T), where 
 1068, 10), as well as to the eponpni of a doubt is thrown out against the 
 tlie tribes. Thus Theocrines was con- genuineness of the oration just men- 
 demned to pay 700 drachmas to the ' tioned. 
 
 cponyraus for inconect accounts, Orat. i ^^i Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1069, 22. 
 c. Theocrin. p. 1326, 6. ! '^"^ ^scliin. c. Tiniarcli. p. oi) sq.
 
 CH. XII.] EXAMPLES OF FIXES. 377 
 
 in case he was convicted, of 1000 drachmas'"'^; a regulation which 
 could not always have been enforced. Whoever dug up olive 
 trees, beyond the number allowed by law, forfeited to the state 
 100 drachmas for each tree, of which a tenth part went to 
 Minerva*^*. A woman conducting herself indecorously in the 
 streets, paid a fine of 1000 drachmas*^\ If a woman went to 
 Eleusis in a carriage, she subjected herself, according to the 
 law of Lycurgus, to a fine of a talent^'^ Whoever brought a 
 foreign dancer upon the stage, forfeited, in the age of Phocion, 
 1000 drachmas. This law, however, only applied to the 
 theatre of Bacchus in the city. Demades brought forward 100, 
 and thus forfeited 100,000 drachmas^". Other fines of 50 and 
 1000 drachmas, with regard to foreigners in the chorus, need 
 not be here mentioned^^^. In the case of embezzlement of 
 public money, the penalty was fixed at double, and in the case 
 of sacred money at ten times the amount^^^ If any person 
 was accused of not having paid a fine awarded by a judicial 
 sentence, or of having retained any property adjudged to the 
 plaintiff, and was convicted in the suit [hiKT] i^ovXrjy, actio rei 
 judicaf{s), the state received from the defendant the same sum 
 that he was bound to pay to the plaintiff ^^''r the same was also 
 the case if the defendant was found guilty of taking forcible 
 possession of any property*^'. The state derived a similar 
 
 ^73 Deniosth. c. Neter. p. 1350, 23; dias (p. 528, 17), av Se f/iKpov ttuvv 
 Petit (Leg. Att. vi. 1,6), has misun- | Tifj-rjixaros a^tov ris \a^r], ^la 8e tovto 
 derstood this law in a most ludicrous | d(Pe\r]TaL, to 'itrov tco drjuoaiw Trpoari/JLtiv 
 manner. j ol vo/jlol KeXevnvo-iv, oaovTrep av t(o 18l- 
 
 ^"* Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1074, 19- ] a>TTj. ]My reason for rejecting this 
 *75 'AKOfr/ieT. See Haii^ocrat. in v. ! inference may be seen from what fol- 
 oTt ;^tXtay, and thence in other glos- lows : of the fact itself I entertain no 
 
 doubt, for expulsion from possession 
 was always considered as violence, 
 even when a creditor was obstructed 
 
 saries. 
 
 276 Petit i. 1, 17. 
 
 277 Plutarch. Phoc. 30; cf. Petit 
 Leg. Att. iii. 4, 3. 
 
 278 See Petit iii. 4, 5. 
 
 279 Demosth. c. Timocrat. passim. 
 *8" Hudtwalcker von den Diateten, 
 
 p. 137 sqq. 
 
 28' Hudtwalcker ut sup. p. 135, note, 
 
 in taking possession of the property 
 pledged for the debt, or when this 
 pledging "and obstruction were only 
 fictions, and consequently as severe a 
 penalty was the consequence of expul- 
 sion from possession, as of an act ot 
 
 wishes to deduce the latter fact from j abstraction by violence. And that in 
 the words of Demosthenes against Mi- | every 8iKt] e^ovXrjs (and not only in the
 
 378 
 
 EXAMPLES OP FINES. 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 profit from condemnations in actions for violence {BUt] 
 ^LaicovY^^; and if any person took a slave from his master as if 
 lie had been a free citizen, he paid to the state the half of the 
 whole fine"\* in all three cases because the state was considered 
 as injured. 
 
 actio rei judicatce) the state received a 
 fine equal in amount to that which was 
 to be made good to the plaintiff, may 
 be also seen from the words of Harpo- 
 cration and Suidas in v. i^ovXrjs diKT] : 
 ol di a.\6vT€S €^ovXt]s koi roJ iXovri 
 eblboaav a d(f)r]povvTO avTOv Koi ra drj- 
 fxoa'm KareTiBecrav ra TLfirjOevra, which 
 passage Hudtwalcker (p. 147) appears 
 not to have undei-stood. It would liave 
 been more convenient if the actio rei 
 judicatce, the issue of wliich was that 
 the same sum was paid to the state as 
 was given in compensation to the 
 plaintiff, had not been called by the 
 same name, hUr) i^oi>kr]s, unless the 
 original hUrj i^ovk-qs, which was a real 
 expulsion from possession, had not 
 been followed by the same conse- 
 quences. Nor do the words of De- 
 mosthenes against Meidias, p. 528, 11, 
 by any means prove that the actio rei 
 judicata was alone followed by a fine 
 to the public, but the orator only cites 
 this one instance, as the other cases, on 
 account of what is afterwards said con- 
 cerning the diKT] (Biaicov, did not appear 
 to require a separate mention. It may 
 be observed, that the reason why the 
 biKT] e^ovXrjs is considered in this place 
 as ovK Ibla is, that it is merely consi- 
 dered in reference to the fine required 
 by the state ; for that in all other re- 
 spects it was iSt'a, Demosthenes must 
 have been well aware. Ovkct inoi-qa-cv 
 is certainly the preferable reading: 
 but the word ovk^tl does not make any 
 opposition between the b'lK-q e^ovXqs as 
 an actio rei judicatce and the dUrj i^ov- 
 Xrjs as an actio unde vi, as if the former 
 could only be called ovk I8ia, and not 
 the latter ; but Demosthenes calls the 
 actio rei judicatce owkcV' Idlav in oppo- 
 
 sition to the foregoing private suit 
 from which it arose. I may also re- 
 mark, that a particular application of 
 the diKT) e^ovXrjs was when it was 
 brought by a mortgagee against the 
 buyer of any property which had been 
 given as security to the former. See 
 the Dissertation on the Mines of 
 Laurium. 
 
 ^^^ Harpocrat. in v. ^laiatv, on the 
 authority of the passage in Demos- 
 thenes against Meidias given in the 
 last note, which refers to the diKTj 
 jBiaioov, and not to the Sixr/ e^ovXrjs, the 
 former being a different kind of action 
 for property taken by violence, but ex- 
 tending only to moveables, for example, 
 slaves. An instance of it occurs in 
 Lysias adv. Pancleon, p. 736. Com- 
 pare Plato de Leg. xi. p. 914 E. It is 
 indeed sufficiently singular that, ac- 
 cording to Suidas, the Biktj c^ovXtjs also 
 applied to moveable property, particu- 
 larly slaves; so that it is not easy to 
 perceive the difference between the 
 dUr] ^uiioov and the Si'/ct; e^ovXrjs. Per- 
 haps it was that the 8lktj ^laicov might 
 be instituted by the possessor against 
 the person who had forcibly abstracted 
 from him some article of moveable 
 property, and that the dUr) e^ovXrjs 
 might be brought on by the person, to 
 whom the moveable property had been 
 adjudged by a judicial verdict, against 
 the possessor who refused to allow hira 
 to take possession; and also by the 
 mortgagee, who had the liglit of seizing 
 the moveable property for non-pay- 
 ment, against the debtor who did not 
 transfer tlie mortgaged property to him. 
 
 ^^^ Concerning this case, in which 
 the offender could be prosecuted by a 
 diKT] (^aijHcrcois, see Orat. c. Theocrin,
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FINES. 
 
 379 
 
 It has been already remarked incidentally in several places^ 
 that in all public actions the plaintiff paid a fine to the state of 
 1000 drachmas, if he did not obtain a fifth part of the suffrages 
 (to Tre/jLTTTOv fiepos tmv yjrTJcpcov fir) /juerdXa^o^v co^Xe ^j^tXta?) ; 
 which penalty could also be enforced, if he dropped a cause 
 already commenced: this last law was not however always 
 apphed in practice, as is proved by the example of Demosthenes, 
 when he abandoned the action against Meidias*^\ The only 
 exemption from this fine was in the case of an eisangelia before 
 the archon^^'; in all other public causes, by whatever names 
 they were distinguished, it was exacted'^^ We find in the 
 ancient authors frequent examples and confirmations of this 
 assertion. Demosthenes expressly proves it with regard to 
 
 p. 1327 sq. Compare the argument 
 and Petit ii. C, 4. According to this 
 law the state received to rjfiia-u tov 
 Tifirjfxaros, by wliich is meant the half 
 of the whole fine, not of the damages 
 acciniing to the plaintiff; i. e. the state 
 received the same sum as the injured 
 person. This, as it appears to me, is 
 evident from a comparison of the dUr] 
 f^ovkr]s and the biio] ^laicop : Plato (ubi 
 Slip.) to a certain degree includes the 
 biKT} e^aipeaecos under the diKr) (:iiaia>v, 
 and then supposes a double reparation 
 of the injury. 
 
 ^* See Taylor's Introduction to the 
 Oration against Meidias. The latter 
 point, viz. the penalty for dropping the 
 action, or for compounding in public 
 suits, is treated of particularly by Hudt- 
 walcker von den Diateten, p. 159 sqq. 
 with so much accuracy, that I have no- 
 thing farther to add. Only the follow- 
 ing words, which occur in p. 168, re- 
 quire some limitation : " It was also 
 allowed to compound even in court, 
 and this was often effected in" criminal 
 cases by the assistance of the judges 
 themselves." For the two instances 
 quoted by ^fatthiso, vol. i. p. 269, of a 
 composition made in court in Isaeus de 
 Dicaeog. Hered. p. 98, and Isocrat. c. 
 
 Callimach. 16, are only in private cases, 
 the former in a diio] ■^cvboyiapTvpiovy 
 the latter in an action for more than 
 10,000 drachmas, which the plaintiff 
 claimed for himself, and not for the 
 state. In the former case indeed the 
 penalty of atimia M^as added, by which 
 however the law suit does not cease to 
 be a private case, as I will show in 
 another place : in the latter the plain- 
 tiff is also apprehensive of the atimia 
 (Isocrat. 15), but evidently only on ac- 
 count of the consequences ensuing upon 
 the loss of the suit ; since, if he had 
 not a fifth part of the votes, he would 
 be compelled to pay the epobelia, and 
 not being able to pay this from liis po- 
 verty, would be prosecuted by the suc- 
 cessful party with a hUri e^ovXrjs, and if 
 condemned in this suit, would become 
 a pubUc debtor. This is the very rea- 
 son why Demosthenes is apprehensive 
 of atimia, with the loss of the epobelia, 
 in the private cause against Aphobus, 
 p. 834, 29, p. 835, 11. 
 
 *^^ See the passages quoted above. 
 
 *^^ Pollux viii. 41, Theophrast. ap. 
 Poll. viii. 53, and in reference to drop- 
 ping the cause see Orat. c. Theocrin. 
 p. 1323, 14 sqq., Demosth. c. Mid. i>. 
 529, 23.
 
 380 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FIXES. 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 the action for assault [hUri or ypa(j>7]v ^pews): the same is 
 evident from other writers with regard to the action for impiety 
 (ypacpyj (iGe^eLa<^Y^' , for incontinency {ypacj)!] eratprjaeajsY^^y 
 and for illegal proceedings (7/3a</)^ TrapavofjLcovY^^ ; and Demos- 
 thenes even refers it to all actions^ aTraycoyal, &c."" With 
 reference to the airaycoyrj, which is another kind of public 
 cause, this liability is several times attributed to it by the 
 ancients-^', as also to the eisangelia*^''; it may equally be proved 
 to have applied in the case of the phasis^^^; so that a distinct 
 testimony is not necessary for the other kinds of public actions. 
 On the other hand, the idea is erroneous, as Heraldus has 
 already shown, that the party condemned by default {in contu- 
 maciam) was obhged to pay 1000 drachmas'"\ The fine, how- 
 ever, which was appointed in public causes underwent, at least 
 at certain periods, some alteration. In an unsuccessful action 
 for illeojal practices mentioned in Demosthenes, we find that 
 the plaintiff w^as only sentenced to a fine of 500 drachmas"^ 
 In other cases an additional fine [Trpoarifjurjixa) appears to have 
 been imposed, as in the case of ^schines, who, in consequence 
 of such fine imposed after the loss of his action against Ctesi- 
 phon, quitted the city of Athens; although nothing certain can 
 be said upon this point, as the ancients themselves were in 
 doubt concerning it"^: also for the most part the plaintiff was 
 subjected to atimia, if he had not the fifth part of the votes 
 with him, and by consequence was debarred from the liberty of 
 instituting certain public suits {ypa^rj, aTraycoyr), e(f>r)yr](Tis, 
 evBcL^cs), nor was he able in an action for impiety to take refuge 
 
 ''^^ Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 702, 5, 
 Plat. Apol. 5. 
 
 '■^^^ Deinosth. c. Androt. p. 599 extr. 
 
 2^^ Demosth. c. Timocmt. p. 701, 1, 
 must be so understood. Comp. also 
 the Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 248, 
 cd. Tubing. 
 
 ^3« C. Androt. p. 001,20. 
 
 29' Deinosth. c. Aristocrat, p. G47, 7, 
 Andocid. c. Alcib. p. 120, Pollux viii. 
 49, Suidas in v. dfjL(f)iopKLa. Cf. Lex. 
 Seg. p. 188, 19, in reference to theft. 
 
 ^^^ Harpocrat. in v. elcrayyeXla, Theo- 
 phrast. ubi sup. 
 
 293 Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1323, 19. 
 
 29^ See Hudtwalcker von den Diii- 
 teten, p. 98 sq. Matthia?, vol. i. p. 26G, 
 is mistaken. To be condemned in 
 contumaciam is ip-q^L-qv 6(p\€iv. 
 
 295 Demosth. de Corona, p. 2fjl, 20, 
 where ras nevraKoo-ias dpaxp-as refers 
 to something customary. 
 
 296 See Lives of the Ten Orators ut 
 sup. and Matthias, p. 272.
 
 CH. X 
 
 !•] 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FINES. 
 
 381 
 
 ill any temple''^, excepting in the case of an eisangelia, probably 
 according to some enactment which was subsequently added*®^ 
 Lastly, the court appears in certain cases to have been authorized 
 to condemn the plaintiff to the same fine at which he had 
 assessed the defendant, as Aristogeiton, having failed in an 
 action for illegal practices against the priestess of Diana of 
 Brauron, was forced to pay the fine of 5 talents, at which he 
 had assessed the defendant''^ The punishment of death, 
 which, according to the statement of Andocides, was the conse- 
 quence of the false information {firjvvaus:) of a mutilator of the 
 Mercuries, appears to have a regulation appointed only for that 
 individual case^"". 
 
 *^^ Concerning the atimia see De- 
 mosth. c. Aristog. i. p. 803, 13, Ando- 
 cid. de jNIyst. p. 17 and 36, whence we 
 learn that this atimia was only partial, 
 Kara npocrTa^iv, that is, according to a 
 certain prohibition that one person 
 might not bring on a ypacfirjy another 
 an evbei^is, &c. See also Schol. De- 
 mosth. ap. Reisk. vol ii. p. 132, 133. 
 According to Genethlius, as quoted by 
 this grammarian, a public accuser could 
 only be sentenced to atimia, if he had 
 not obtained the fifth part of the votes 
 in three law suits; t. e. because Andro- 
 tion had not been made ari/xoy, for 
 having once lost an action of this kind : 
 this assertion is however im tenable, 
 nor can it be proved that Androtion, 
 after losing the ypcK^rj dae^elas, wns 
 not arifjios Kara TrpocrTa^iv, so that he 
 could not any more ypacf)€a6cu in the 
 more limited sense : and even suppos- 
 ing that this was not then the conse- 
 quence of losing the cause, it must be 
 borne in mind that at Athens the letter 
 of the law was not always attended to. 
 The law might therefore have pre- 
 scribed atimia. and yet its ordinances 
 have been disobeyed. The same was 
 the case with the law which imposed a 
 pimishment for gi\'ing \ip public ac- 
 tions, of which I have just spoken. It 
 ismoreover evident, that whoever failed 
 to pay the fine of 1000 drachmas was 
 
 also su})ject to the separate kind of 
 atimia imposed upon public debtors. 
 Whether atimia was the immediate 
 consequence of dropping a public ac- 
 tion is not manifest. From Demos- 
 thenes adv. Mid. p. 548, 7, and there 
 Ulpian, it may be concluded that 
 atimia had been appointed by law 
 (only however the partial atimia in 
 reference to bringing on actions of this 
 kind), as Heraldus Aniraadv. vii. 16, 
 20, assumes, without any interference 
 on the part of the state; for the plain- 
 tiff, says Demosthenes, subjects him- 
 self to the atimia by dropping the suit, 
 without mentioning that the state sen- 
 tenced him to it. But we may adopt 
 the supposition advanced by Hudt- 
 walcker in p. 162, that the seceding 
 plaintiff was condemned to a fine of 
 1000 diachmas, and made himself 
 arifxos by failing to pay it, inasmuch 
 as he had then become a public debtor, 
 and thus actually artpos, although per- 
 haps he was not considered as such, as 
 gradually they ceased to exact the 
 payment of the fines, and to treat the 
 defaulters as serarii. 
 
 29« Poll. viii. 53, from Theophrastus. 
 
 ^^^ Dinarch. in Aristog. p. 82. 
 
 SO" See Matth. p. 270, 271. This 
 information must be distinguished from 
 the ypa(j>ri dcre^eiaf.
 
 EXAMPLES OF FINES. 
 
 [iJK. III. 
 
 The fines (rtfiri/jLaTa) which were fixed against the plaintiff 
 were for the most part much higher. In cases indeed in which 
 the senate decided, as in certain kinds of eisangeUa, the defen- 
 dant escaped easily, as the senate was not able to inflict a fine 
 of more than 500 drachmas; if however a fine of this amount 
 appeared too small, they referred the case to a court of justice. 
 An instance of a very inconsiderable fine is afforded in the 
 cause of Theophemus, who by the concession of his accuser 
 was only condemned to an additional fine {7rpo<TTifJLr)fjba) of 25 
 drachmas,b esides the restitution of what the state claimed from 
 him as public property^"'. Phrynichus was condemned in a 
 public action to a fine of 1000 drachmas for the representation 
 of his play called the Taking of Miletus^^*. In the action for 
 impiety {ypacprj aae^eias;) brought against Socrates, his accu- 
 sers made it a capital crime; he himself however fixed the 
 penalty at 1 mina, and afterwards, upon the injudicious re- 
 commendation of his friends, at 30 minas, or according to 
 others at only 25 drachmas'*"^. The common fine imposed by 
 the judges appears to have been 10,000 drachmas^"*: 5 talents 
 are mentioned in the case of Anaxagoras^°% although the 
 accounts of the misfortunes of this philosopher at Athens do 
 not all agree ^^^th this fact. A fine of 10,000 drachmas also 
 occurs in the public suit for assault, and also as a penalty for 
 sycophancy^ °^. In the action for false citation {ypa<f)r) s^evho- 
 KkT^reias) death is mentioned as the punishment, but mitigated 
 upon the representation of the plaintiff to a fine of a talent^"^. 
 Fines of a very large amount were imposed in the actions 
 for illegal practices {ypacprj m-apavofiwv), as much as 5, 10, or 
 15 talents, although they w^ere sometimes lowered, for ex- 
 ample, a fine of 15 talents was diminished to 1. We even 
 find that ^schines fixed a fine of 50 talents against Cte- 
 siphon, and Lycinus a fine of 100 against Philocrates^''^; both 
 
 ^•^^ Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. p. 
 1152, compare Pollux viii. 51. 
 
 3°=^ Herod, vi. 21, and there the 
 commentatoi-s. 
 
 ^3 Plat. Apol. 28, and there Fisclier. 
 
 ^* Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 
 "'*'' Diog. Laert. ii. 12. 
 
 »"« Aristoph. A v. I04fi, 1052, Lysias 
 c. Agorat. p. 488. 
 
 ^'7 Orat. c. Nicostrat. p. 1252, 15. 
 
 ^"8 Diog. Laert. in Vit. Theophrast. 
 Dinarch. c. Aristog. p. 82, 83, Orat. c.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FIXES. 
 
 a83 
 
 these persons were acquitted, which however must not he con- 
 sidered as an usual occurrence. It was no douht by an action 
 of this kind that Demades was condemned to a fine of 10, or, 
 according to ^Uan, of 100 talents, for having proposed to pay 
 divine honours to Alexander^°^ The former was probably the 
 sum that was actually adjudged, the latter the original proposal 
 of the accuser. 
 
 These fines were made a productive branch of the public 
 revenue by the injustice of the demagogues, by party hatred, 
 and the litigious disposition which prevailed. The popular 
 leaders, seldom guided by purely moral principles, raised 
 themselves by flattering the people, and by the lavish admi- 
 nistration and distribution of the public money. The majo- 
 rity of them however so little forgot their own gain, -vvhen they 
 had reached their high station, that they omitted no means 
 of enriching themselves, and the people on the other hand 
 rejoiced in condemning and overthrowing them. What great 
 demagogue was there who did not meet with an unhappy des- 
 tiny ? Was not this the fate of Miltiades, Themistocles, Aris- 
 tides, Timotheus, and Demosthenes? And fortunate was he 
 who escaped with the payment of a heavy fine, while others 
 suffered the penalty of death, or were condemned to forfeiture 
 of property, or to exile. Thrasybulus, son of the restorer of 
 the freedom of Athens (who himself, if he had not died, would 
 have been capitally condemned), paid a fine of 10 talents^' % 
 probably by an action for malversation in an embassy {<ypa(l>r} 
 irapairpea^elas), CalUas the Torchbearer concluded a most 
 advantageous and honourable peace wdth the king of Persia, 
 according to which no army was to approach the coast within a 
 day^s march of cavalry, and no armed Persian vessel was to 
 appear in the Grecian seas; yet although he obtained much 
 celebrity by these negotiations, as Plutarch relates in the Life of 
 Cimon, he was condemned to a fine of 50 talents, when he ren- 
 
 Theocrin. p. 1323, 3, (cf. p. 1331, 19, 
 p. 1332, 5, 17, 22,) and p. 1336, De- 
 mosth. c. Mid. p. 573, 17, Orat. c. 
 Neser. p. 1347, 10, (p. 1348, 1,) De- 
 mosth. de Corona, ^sch. de Fals. Leg. 
 
 p. 198,190. 
 
 2«» Athen. vi. p. 251, B. ^lian. V. 
 H. V. 12. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 431, 
 14.
 
 384 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FINES. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 dered an account of his official conduct, for having taken 
 bribes'' '. And how large was the number of those who were 
 condemned to severe punishments for treason or bribery! 
 Cleon was compelled to pay 5 talents, probably not, as the 
 Schohast of Aristophanes''* supposes, for having injured the 
 knights, but for having taken bribes from the allies, in order to 
 procure a mitigation of their tributes; and to omit the fine of 
 50 minas, which Aristides is stated (probably without truth) to 
 have paid for having received bribes'' % Timotheus was con- 
 demned upon the same grounds to a fine of 100 talents by an 
 indictment for treason {'ypa<j)r] TrpoBocrLas:), a sum greater than 
 ever had been paid until that occasion: nine parts out of ten 
 were however remitted to his son Conon, and the tenth he was 
 forced to expend upon the repair of the walls for which Athens 
 was indebted to his grandfather' '^ Demosthenes was sen- 
 tenced to a fine of 50 talents by an action for bribery {ypacf)!] 
 BcopoBoKLa<;), and also thrown into prison"^; the latter punish- 
 ment having doubtless been imposed in addition by the court 
 {TTpocrTL/jLTjfjba). According to the strict law he should have 
 paid ten times the amount of the sum received; five times the 
 amount is however the only fine mentioned, and even this he 
 was unable to pay^'^: nor can we determine how this fine was 
 calculated, as the statements of the sums received are so con- 
 tradictory, that Dinarchus"' speaks of 20 talents in gold, and 
 refers to the Areopagus for authority, with whom Plutarch"® 
 agrees, who relates that he received 20 talents in a royal golden 
 goblet; whereas others speak of 30 talents, and even of so 
 
 2' ^ Demosth. ut sup. p. 428. Con- 
 cerning the embassy (Olymp. 82, 4, b.c. 
 44y,) see Diod. xii. 4, Herod, vii. 151. 
 
 ''^ Acham. 5, where the statement 
 of Theopompus should be particularly 
 attended to. It aj^pears that the 
 kuights Avere the accusers, and that 
 Cleon by mitigation of the fine only 
 paid the sum which he had embezzled. 
 The proceeding was without doubt the 
 ypacjif] dcopoboKias- See the second 
 argument to tlie Kuights. 
 
 ^'^^ Plutarch. Aristid. 26. 
 
 ^'* Dinarch.c. Demosth. p. 11. Iso- 
 crat. de Antidos. p. 75, cd. Orell- Ne- 
 pos Timoth. 3, 4, cf. Vit. Dec. Orat, p. 
 234, 235, ed. Tiibing. 
 
 ^'^ Plutarch. Demosth. 26. That it 
 was a ypa(f)rj dcopodoicias is evident from 
 the case itself, and from the Lives of 
 the Ten Orators, p. 264. 
 
 3'« Vit. Dec. Orat. ut sup. 
 
 ^^7 C. Demosth. p. 40. 
 
 ^'8 Vit. Demosth. 25.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 EXAMPLES OF FINES. 
 
 385 
 
 small a sum as 1000 darics^^'. Demosthenes remained in debt 
 30 talents of his fine, which upon his recal were remitted to 
 him for the building of an altar'^**. Miltiades was accused of 
 treason, and condemned to pay 50 talents, not for a compensa- 
 tion, as Nepos ignorantly asserts, but according to the usual 
 form of assessing the offence. The fine was paid by his son^*^ 
 Even before this occasion Miltiades had been sentenced to a 
 fine of 30 talents'". Cimon himself narrowly escaped being 
 condemned to death for a supposed intent to overthrow the 
 existing government, which penalty was commuted for a fine of 
 50 talents'*\ The illustrious Pericles was vehemently accused, 
 after the second invasion of Attica by the Lacedaemonians, the 
 people being dissatisfied with his method of carrying on the 
 war, and particularly with the abandonment of their own coun- 
 try to the enemy ; and the Athenians were not contented, as 
 Thucydides says^**, until they had sentenced him to a fine. The 
 highest sum stated was, according to Plutarch^**, 50 talents, the 
 lowest 15; the former was probably the assessment of the 
 accuser, the latter of the court. Fines of a less amount did 
 however occur in important cases, as for example a fine of only 
 3 talents in an indictment for treason®*®. 
 
 Chapter XIII. 
 
 The Public Debtors. Nature of the Legal Remedies against them. 
 
 Every person who failed to pay a fine owing to the state was 
 reckoned among the public debtors {ol tw Srj/jLO(TL(p 6(j)€L\ovTes), 
 of whom some mention has been already made in connection 
 
 '!«» Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 264, 267- 
 
 ^'^'^ Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 264, and Pho- 
 tius. Plutarch. Demosth. 27, who how- 
 ever also mentions 50 talents in this 
 place. 
 
 321 Herod, vi. 136, Plutarch Ci- 
 mon. 4, Nepos Cimon. 1. 
 
 "^ Orat. c. Aristogit. ii. p. 802, 18. 
 
 ^" Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 688, 
 25. 
 
 ^24 ii. G5. 
 
 325 Pericl. 35. To the former be- 
 longs the author of the speech against 
 Aristogeiton ii. ut sup. Diodorus, 
 with his usual exaggeration, mentions 
 80 talents, xii. 45. 
 
 2"^'' Demostli. c. Timocrat p. 740, 15. 
 
 2 C
 
 386 THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. [bK. III« 
 
 with the account of the farmers of the public duties*, but the 
 main investigation properly belongs to this part of the book. 
 
 The pubhc debtors were of different kinds, either farmers of 
 public property or their sureties, or purchasers, for example, of 
 mines^", or persons who had been sentenced to a public fine, or 
 who had borrowed property from the state, and had not re- 
 placed it at the appointed time, as, for instance, ships' furniture 
 belonging to the state from the public storehouses^ °; also such 
 as had not paid rents or fines accruing to the funds of the tem- 
 ples^*', although it is not entirely clear whether the whole seve- 
 rity of the law against public debtors was at all times applicable 
 to the latter class of defaulters. It is certain that those who 
 w^ere in arrear for the property-tax {elcr(f>opa) were treated less 
 severely, nor do I find that they were classed with the public 
 debtors; a regulation which is perfectly reasonable. Whoever 
 had purchased or was in possession of any public property, was 
 a personal debtor, and by parity of reasoning, whoever had 
 failed to pay a fine after it had become due; these therefore 
 might be subjected to atimia and imprisonment, besides other 
 penalties: whereas the property-tax was not a personal debt, 
 but a debt merely attaching upon property, for which no one 
 could be imprisoned, or treated in the manner of the public 
 debtors; it therefore remained unpaid without any evil conse- 
 quences for the person taxed, until the state, pressed by pecu- 
 niary difficulties, determined upon a final and complete collec- 
 tion, and then it could resort to the property of the debtor, if 
 he refused to pay^^". 
 
 To ascertain at what time any person became a public 
 
 • Above cli. viii. 
 
 3*7 Demosth. c. Pantsen. p. 973, 6, 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. 
 p. 1145,25. 
 
 ^^^ Thence the permission to take 
 tlie property of a citizen for a fine of 
 tliis kind. (See Corp. Inscript. No. 
 123, § 2.) But the payment of double 
 
 this belongs the case quoted in note 
 lfi2. 
 
 ^^^ The truth of this statement is 
 proved beyond a doubt by Demosth. 
 c. Androt. p. 608 — CIO. Cf. Lys. c. 
 Philocrat. p. 832. The poletse also 
 were entrusted with the duty of sell- 
 ing the property of those who re- 
 
 the amount after the ninth prytaneia mained in debt for tlieir property- 
 does not appear to have been required taxes. Photius in v. TrwXj/rai, Suidas 
 either in this or many other cases. To in v. TrcoXr/r^f.
 
 CH. XIII.] THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 38? 
 
 debtor requires a separate investigation. With regard to pur- 
 chasers and farmers of public property, and their sureties, 
 it is evident, that they became public debtors as soon as 
 they exceeded the appointed term of payment. It is more 
 difficult to decide as to those who had to pay any kind 
 of fine, whether arising from action, the passing of official 
 accounts, or a judicial sentence^^*; at the same time every 
 thing seems to show that the party condemned became a public 
 debtor immediately after his sentence, if he did not pay the fine 
 upon the spot. With respect to the public action for assault 
 {ypacprj v/Specos), the ancient law enacted that if the defendant 
 was condemned to a fine, he should pay it eleven days after 
 judgment, and that if he should not be able to pay immediately, 
 he should be imprisoned until the payment^^^; it appears, how- 
 ever, that afterwards, if any person assaulted a free citizen, he 
 could be detained in confinement until he had paid, according 
 to the law in Demosthenes^^^. In this law it is supposed that 
 properly the fine was to be paid immediately after every sen- 
 tence, and that the party so sentenced should be instantly 
 thrown into prison^^^: the additional provision that if he did not 
 pay down the fine upon the spot, he should pay it eleven days 
 after, merely fixes the extreme point, after which he was 
 proceeded against with greater severity. From the first until 
 the eleventh day he was a public debtor, as being under 
 obligation to pay; after the eleventh the payment was no 
 longer received as before, but he was subject to the severe 
 penalty of the regular payment of twice the sum, and if this 
 was not immediately made, confiscation of property. In the 
 case of other debtors the extreme period was the ninth pryta- 
 neia, and they could be imprisoned until that period. For a 
 person condemned in a public suit for an assault, it was provided 
 as an additional punishment that the eleventh day should be 
 the extreme period of payment, and that the party condemned 
 should be put in chains, or at least kept in confinement. As 
 
 3^' The different kinds are enume- 
 rated by Andocides de Myst. p. 35. 
 See above, note 155. 
 
 "^^■^ iEsch. c. Timarch. p. 42. 
 ^^^ C. Mid. p. 529. 
 s'^ Cf. Demostb. c. .Mid. p. 529, 27. 
 2 c 2
 
 388 
 
 THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 
 
 [bK. Ill, 
 
 then this law is not opposed to the account already given, so it 
 is completely confirmed by the express provision, that from the 
 day that any person was sentenced to a fine or transgressed the 
 law (d(fi rjs av 6(j>\7] rj Trapa/Sr} rbv vojiov rj to -yfrricpto-pLa)^ he 
 should become a public debtor, even if his name had not been 
 reported by the practores"*. This enactment contains two pro- 
 visions, according to the difference of the case. In offences 
 which were not proved, and which required an assessment, it 
 was necessary that a sentence should be passed before the indi- 
 vidual could become a public debtor, as e. g. in the common 
 action (ypa<j)r)): if however the offence was evident, and the 
 fine appointed by law, as is implied in a case of information 
 (evBec^ts), the offender became a public debtor from the moment 
 of the transgression, and the action an information against him 
 as a public debtor^^^ It was not by the enrolment of the name 
 that the party became a public debtor, but this latter form was 
 only a consequence of his being one. 
 
 The registration of the names was made for the public trea- 
 sury upon tablets in the temple of Minerva on the Acropolis, 
 the sums due being also noted^^^ This duty belonged to the 
 practores, whose office it was to exact the fines^^^: thence a 
 person registered upon the Acropolis {iyyeypafjbfievos iv ^AKpo- 
 iroXei) always means a public debtor^^^ Whoever owed any 
 money to the temple of Minerva, to the other gods, or to the 
 heroes of the tribes, was equally liable to an information {evSec- 
 ^is), if he was not registered^*^; the registration took place 
 before the treasurers of the goddess, and of the other gods, and 
 before the king-archon, with the latter of which authorities, 
 those persons were probably registered who owed any money to 
 the heroes of the tribes^"". The registration of the thesmo- 
 thetse {iyypacprj Oea^oOerwv), which occurs once, connected 
 with a registration made by the practores^ ^'^, is probably nothing 
 
 33* Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1328, 10, p. 
 1337, 26 sqq. 
 
 a^« Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1337, 1338. 
 
 =«7 Orat. c. Aristog. i. p. 791, 11, 
 Harpocration and Suidas in v. yj/evdey- 
 ypacPf], Suidas in v. ^€vbeyypa(f)os dUr] 
 and aypa(j)iov bUr}, Sec. 
 
 ^^^ See book ii. ch. 4. 
 
 ^^' Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesibul. ut 
 sup. 
 
 ^^^ Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1326, 2—6. 
 
 ^*^ Cf. Andocid. de Myst. p. 36, 
 extr. 
 
 3" Orat. c. Aristog. i. p. 778, 18.
 
 CM. XIII.] 
 
 THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 
 
 389 
 
 else than the information which the thesmothetae, in their capa- 
 city of superintendants of the court, gave to the practores, 
 in the regular course of business, with regard to the sen- 
 tence which had been passed ; this registration on the part 
 of the court was the necessary condition for the other which 
 was made by the practores. Whoever paid his fine after regis- 
 tration, was erased either wholly or in part, according to the 
 amount paid^''\ As an information (eVSetf^y) could be laid 
 against such persons as were not registered, so were those 
 alone who had been improperly erased subject to the action for 
 non-registration (St/ct; dypacpcov), which therefore could not be 
 instituted against a person who had never been registered^**. 
 
 3-3 Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1338, 8. 
 An instance occm's in Corp. Inscript. 
 No. 158. 
 
 ^'^ The author of the speech against 
 Theocrines, p. 1337, 1338, 7—27, refers 
 the ypa<pff. aypacfiiov to those who had 
 been illegally released, in opposition 
 to the evdet^is against those who had 
 never been registered : cf Harpocrat. 
 Snid. Etymol. in v. dypa(})iov, Pollux 
 viii. 54. Zonaras in v. dypacfiiov diKT] 
 is imperfect. On the other hand, 
 Hesychius (in v. dypacfilov diKij) and 
 Lex. Seg. p. 199, state that tlie yp(i4>V 
 dypa(f)iov was instituted against the 
 debtors who were not registered. He- 
 sychius is followed by Hemsterhuis 
 (ad Polluc), and by AVesseling (ad 
 Petit, iv. 9, 19, 20,) who transcribes 
 the note of the latter, accusing the 
 author of the speech against Theo- 
 crines, notwithstanding his express 
 reference to the law, of intentional 
 perversion of justice. Hemsterhuis 
 however brings forward but weak argu- 
 ments, and Hesychius, whose collec- 
 tion shows upon the whole but little 
 legal knowledge, together with the 
 author of the Rhetorical Lexicon, or 
 their authority, probably only inferred 
 their statement from the name ; nor 
 could the orator have uttered so direct 
 a falsehood, particularly since the 
 
 apparent force of the word was against 
 him, and he must have known that 
 the law had assigned to it a more 
 limited meaning. It is unquestionably 
 true that an evdei^ts might be laid 
 against public debtors, when they held 
 an official situation (Liban. Argument, 
 ad Demosth. in Androt. Suid. in v. 
 ivdeiKvvvai, Zonaras in v. ev^ei^is); 
 but manifestly it does not follow from 
 this that it might not be laid against a 
 debtor who had not been registered, 
 without any reference to public offices. 
 But because a person who was not re- 
 gistered might at any moment obtain 
 a place in the public administration, it 
 Mas natural to allow the evdei^is to 
 be laid against him in order that he 
 might be registered, and thus be cirtfxoi 
 and excluded from holding public offi- 
 ces. This was as it were an cvdei^ts 
 dypa<pLov, in which the offence was 
 evident, and the penalty although of 
 small amount was fixed by law; if, on 
 the other hand, any person was re- 
 leased after he had been registered, he 
 was prosecuted by a ypa(f)fj dypa(f)iovy 
 as in this case there were many points 
 to investigate, the question was more 
 intricate, and the offence so consti- 
 tuted, that it appeared to admit of a 
 very various assessment. Tlie diffi- 
 culty is removed, when it is perceived
 
 390 
 
 THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 Whoever, on the other hand, falsely declared that he had been 
 registered, was subject to the action for false registration {hUr) 
 -^jrevBeyypaipT]^), whether he owed nothing or less than the sum 
 stated in the register ; if he had paid, and yet was registered 
 again, probably also if he was not erased, the action for con- 
 spiracy {ypacprj ySouXevcreft)?) applied^*^: in both cases if the 
 plaintiff was successful, his name was erased, and the defendant 
 became indebted to the state for an equal sum^'*^ 
 
 A punishment immediately connected with the condition of 
 a public debtor is infamy [aTiixla) or civil death^*^, an inquiry 
 into the diflferent degrees of which is not necessary for our pur- 
 pose. Imprisonment, on the other hand, was by no means an 
 immediate consequence of a public debt, except when the law 
 expressly provided it, as e. g, against a plaintiff who was con- 
 demned in a public action for assault, of which I have just 
 spoken, and in the eisangelia, if the accused was sentenced to a 
 fine, according to the law of Timocrates^". In cases however 
 in which the law did not prescribe imprisonment, it was added 
 by the increase of punishment (TrpoarLfjLijfxa) if the law per- 
 mitted it^*^. In this manner Demosthenes and Miltiades were 
 cast into prison, where the latter died^'", and according to 
 Nepos^'^, his son Cimon shared the same fate, as having 
 inherited the debt, of which however Plutarch knew nothing, 
 and Plato^^' in the case of Socrates speaks of imprisonment 
 
 that the stress is upon ypa(f)T}, and not 
 upon dypacpiov. I have therefore fol- 
 lowed the statements in the oration 
 against Theocrines, both with regard 
 to the evbei^is and the ypa(j)Tj dypa- 
 (f>iov, without paying any attention to 
 the learned writers mentioned above. 
 
 '■^*^ Suid. in vv. -^evdifs iyypa(f>r] and 
 yj/evdeyypacPos Blkt], 
 
 ^*^ Orat. c. Aristogit. i. p. 792, 3, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 317. I pass over the 
 ypa(f)r] "^evdoKXrjTcias {ylr€v8oK\r](Tias) 
 which Hai-pocration (and Lex. Seg. p. 
 317) also refers to the public debtors. 
 The cases which the grammarian al- 
 luded to were accidentally connected 
 with public debts. For the same reason 
 the inaccurate author of the Lexicon 
 
 Segueranum, p. 194, 21, limits the 
 ypn(f)rj ylrevdoKkTjTelas to the false sum- 
 mons in the action els efjLcfiavcov Kard- 
 (TTaaiv, from Demosth. c. Nicostrat. p. 
 1251. 
 
 ^^"^ Andocid. de Myster. p. 35, Orat. 
 c. Theocrin. p. 1326, 20, c. Neser. p. 
 1347, 10, Demosth. c.Timocrat. p. 743, 
 19, c. Androt. p. 603 ext., Orat. c. 
 Aristogit. i. p. 771, 6, cf. Petit, iv. 9, 
 12—14. 
 
 ^*^ Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 721. 
 
 ^*^ See above chap. viii. 
 
 "° Herod, vi. 136, Plutarch. Cim. 4, 
 Nepos Miltiad. 7, Cim. i, 
 
 "^ Cim. i. 
 
 "^ Apol. p. 37 B.
 
 CM. XIII.J THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 391 
 
 until the debt is paid^ as a customary circumstance; although it 
 is evident from other passages that it did not always take place, 
 since no allusion is made to imprisonment in places where it 
 must necessarily have been mentioned, if it had been generally 
 inflicted"^ 
 
 During the continuance of the atimia and imprisonment the 
 public debtors, with the exception of those who received sen- 
 tence in a public cause for assault, were permitted to pay at any 
 time before the ninth prytaneia: if the payment was not made 
 before this term the debt was doubled, and the next step was 
 confiscation of the property, in order to raise from it the amount 
 of the double debt^^^, which procedure, however, Timocrates 
 endeavoured to restrain by a law, as has been stated above at 
 full length^^\ An instance of the fine being doubled is afforded 
 by the speech against Theocrines"®; the same circumstance is 
 also mentioned to have taken place in the case of a purchaser of 
 a mine, who had delayed the term of payment^". The severity 
 of this law (the injurious effects of which are set forth in the 
 speech against Neaera) was farther increased by the debt de- 
 scending to the sons as heirs to the estate, although this provi- 
 sion may have been necessary in order to prevent concealment 
 or secret transfer of the property: thus the atimia, if the 
 imprisonment was remitted, passed on to the children^^% until 
 they paid what their father owed, as, among many others, the 
 instance of Cimon may show^^^ Also, if the father was not regis- 
 tered, and the exaction of the money owing had been omitted, 
 the children were considered by the law as debtors to the state^^°; 
 and the debt even went by inheritance to the grandson^^\ 
 
 No fine that had been once adjudged could be re- 
 
 S53 Andcc. de Myst. p. 35, Orat. c. j """ Oiat. c. Neser. p. 1347, 11, De- 
 Neaer. p. 1347, aud in other places. j inosth. c. Androt. p. G03, extr. See 
 25* Andoc. de Myst. Orat. c. Neser. | Petit iv. 9, 15. 
 
 ut sup. Liban. Argum. ad Orat. i. c. 
 Aristogit. Ilarpocrat. in v. ddiKLOv. 
 
 2" See above chap. viii. 
 
 35« P. 1322, 3. 
 
 3*7 Deraosth. c. Panteen. p. 973, 6. 
 Compare p. 9C8, 8, and the argument 
 p. 064, 18. 
 
 3^^ Nepos Cim. 1, Plutarch. Cim. 4. 
 Cf. Demosth. c. Bceot. de Norn. p. 998, 
 25. 
 
 3^" Orat. c. Theocrin. p. 1327, 21 
 sqq. 
 
 3«i Ibid. p. 1326, 29, p. 1327, 4. Cf. 
 Demosth. c. Aphob. ii. iuit.
 
 392 
 
 THE PUBLIC DEBTORS. 
 
 [bk. hi. 
 
 mitted'", except upon one condition, which will be immedi- 
 ately explained: if the state was willing to grant this, it was 
 necessary to have recourse to a form, by which the debt appeared 
 to be paid, although in reality it had not; and of this nature 
 is the building of the altar which was allowed to Demosthenes. 
 Nor could any debtor who was under atimia apply for a remission 
 of the debt and atimia; if he petitioned in person, he was exposed 
 to an information (eVSetft?); if another person petitioned for 
 him, his property was forfeited; if the proedrus put it to the 
 vote, he was himself placed under atimia. It was necessary 
 that 6000 Athenians should give express permission by a 
 decree which was passed by secret votes in tablets, before it 
 could be debated in the public assembly whether a public debtor 
 should be remitted his debt, and be reinstated in his former 
 situation^"^ 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 
 The Confiscation of Property. 
 
 Aristophanes mentions the property confiscated and publicly 
 sold {Brj/jLcoTrpara) as a separate branch of the public revenue^"*; 
 concerning which an account was presented to the people in the 
 first assembly of every prytaneia^^^ The lists of such forfeitures 
 were posted upon tablets in diflferent places, as was the case at 
 Eleusis, with the catalogues of the articles which accrued to the 
 temple of Ceres and Proserpine, from such persons as had com- 
 mitted any oiSfence against these deities^®^ 
 
 The penalty of confiscation of property, however unjust 
 towards the heirs, who are innocent of the offence; however 
 melancholy its consequences to families^®^; and however evident 
 its tendency to produce unjust accusations and decisions among 
 
 8«* Petit iv. 9, W. 
 
 ««3 Petit iv. 9, 22. Tliis is the cideia 
 trepl Ta)v o<f>€i\6vT(>iv ockttc \eyeiv i^elvai 
 Koi €'m'\lrr)(f)i(civ, Andocid. de Myst. 
 p. 36. 
 
 ^'''* Aristoph. Vesp. 657, aud the 
 
 Scholiast; also Schol. Eq. 103. 
 
 3" Pollux viii. 95, Schol. ^schin. 
 vol. iii. p. 739. 
 
 ««« Pollux ix. 97. 
 
 "^' Orat. c. Neaer. p. 1347.
 
 CH. XIV.] THE CONFISCATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 393 
 
 the persons who would gain by the condemnation of the 
 accused, was yet one of the commonest sources of revenue in 
 ancient days, and all writers, in particular Lysias, afford exam- 
 ples of it. Besides the proceedings against the public debtors 
 and their sureties^^% which have been already mentioned, the 
 law enacted in very many instances the confiscation of property, 
 with infamy, banishment, slavery, or death; the three latter 
 punishments always brought the loss of property with them : 
 this was not however the case with banishment by ostracism 
 [ocTTpaKLafjLo^), which differed essentially from simple exile 
 (<^f7^, d€L(j)vyLa), It is particularly mentioned that the pro- 
 perty of those persons was confiscated who were condemned for 
 wilful murder^®% who were banished by the Areopagus^ ^*^, or 
 were guilty of sacrilege and treason^^'; or again, persons who 
 endeavoured to establish a tyranny, or to dissolve the demo- 
 cracy. Thus the property of Pisistratus was sold several times 
 to Callias: any person who killed a tyrant received the half of 
 his property^^"* ; whoever married a foreigner to a citizen, under 
 pretence that she was a citizen, subjected himself to atimia, and 
 his property was forfeited, of which the third part was received 
 by the accuser: if a foreigner married a female citizen, his person 
 and property were sold, and the third part of the proceeds was 
 also received by the accuser^'^. In the age of Demosthenes, 
 any foreign woman who married a citizen was sold as a slave, 
 but probably only in case she pretended to be a citizen. Resi- 
 dent aliens were sold, together with their property, if they exer- 
 cised the rights of citizenship, failed to pay the protection 
 money, or lived without a patron {TrpoardrrisY''*, 
 
 These are particular cases selected out of a large number : for 
 it was a favourite practice of the Athenians to multiply occasions 
 
 368 Besides that which has been 
 already remarked in speaking of the 
 letting of duties, see Orat. c. Nicos- 
 trat. p. 1255, 1. 
 
 3«» Demosth. c.Mid. p. 528, c. Aris- 
 tocrat, p. 634, 23. 
 
 370 Pollux viii. 99. 
 
 '7^ Petit viii. 4, 4. 
 
 3'* Andoc. de Myst. p. 49 sqq. Petit 
 
 iii. 2, 15. Comp. also Xenoph. Hellen. 
 i. 7, 10, Herod, vi. 121. After the 
 archonship of Euclid (b.c. 403) this 
 law did not apply to the time previous 
 to that year; but it doubtless was con- 
 sidered to be in force for the subse- 
 quent time. 
 
 373 Petit vi. 1, 5, 6. 
 
 37* Petit ii. 5, 2, sqq.
 
 S94 
 
 THE CONFISCATION OF PROPERTY. [bK. III. 
 
 for the confiscation of property, and they endeavoured above 
 all to entrap the resident aliens, as Diceearchus remarks of his 
 times^^'. The demagogues also favoured these measures, for the 
 purpose of increasing their private gains and the public revenue, 
 and of providing donations of money to be distributed among 
 the multitude, which was the policy of Cleon'^'. At Megara 
 the penalty of banishment was often resorted to, for the sake of 
 the consequent confiscation of property, and the most crafty and 
 malicious calumnies were circulated against the wealthy, with a 
 view to obtain their possessions^'^ The desire of gain destroyed 
 all sense of equity: and injustice was attended by its natural 
 consequences and penalties; for the multitude of exiles, restless 
 in their places of banishment, and eager to return, created dis- 
 traction and disturbances in their native country. 
 
 It should be remarked, that, besides the confiscation of the 
 whole property, there were other cases in which only a particu- 
 lar sort of property accrued to the state; thus, for example, 
 mines which were in the possession of private individuals, 
 reverted to the state on the violation of the laws and non-per- 
 formance of the obligations under which they were hekP"^; com- 
 modities again were forfeited to the state, if the payment of the 
 custom duties was fraudulently avoided, and also if a false 
 measure was used^'^ It is, moreover, probable that the pro- 
 perty of persons who died without heirs belonged to the state. 
 This event may, however, have been equally rare with the 
 analogous case of a person appointing the state his heir; as we 
 read that Callias made over his property to the people, in case 
 he should die childless^ ^*'. 
 
 Notwithstanding the frequency of confiscation of property, 
 the state appears to have derived little essential benefit from it; 
 as we see that the plunder of the church property has for the 
 
 '^7s Geograph. Min.vol. ii. p. 9. See 
 Dodwell's Diss. p. 6. 
 
 ?76 Aristoj) 1. Eq. 103, and Scholia, 
 in which ovcricov should be written 
 instead of Bvaiav. 
 
 377 Aristot. PoHt. V. 5. 
 
 ^78 Oiat. c. Phacnipp. p. 1039. 20. 
 
 See the Dissei-tation upon the Silver 
 Mines of Laurium. 
 
 ^7^ For the former point see book 
 iii. ch. 8, for the latter, Corp. Inscript. 
 No. 123. 
 
 381 Andocid. c. Alcibiad. p. 118.
 
 CH. XIV.] THE CONFISCATION OF PROPERTY. 395 
 
 most part been of little advantage to modern states. Consider- 
 able sums were squandered in this manner, such as the property 
 of Diphilus, which amounted to 160 talents; in many cases a 
 part of the property was received by the accuser, and in most, 
 as appears from the above-quoted examples, the third part. In 
 certain cases, the person who informed against public debtors 
 received three parts of the confiscated possession^^'; this regu- 
 lation appears however to have been confined to concealed pro- 
 perty, which was discovered by the informer. A tithe of the 
 property of persons condemned for treason, or for having endea- 
 voured to subvert the democracy" ^% and probably also of all or 
 of most other forfeitures, belonged of right to Minerva of the 
 Parthenon. Many kinds of property were received by the tem- 
 ples without any deduction, so that nothing passed into the 
 public cofFers^^^: and how great must have been the losses occa- 
 sioned by fraud or by sale of property under its value. " You 
 know,^^ says a person in Lysias threatened with confiscation of 
 property^ ^*, " that part of my property will be plundered by 
 these persons (his adversaries), and that what has considerable 
 value will be sold at a low price;" the community, he remarks, 
 derives less profit from the forfeiture, than if the proprietors 
 retained the property, and performed the services annexed to it 
 by law. Again, the offender frequently concealed his property 
 under a fictitious name, or relations and friends claimed it from 
 the state, and, finally, the accused sought to excite pity, by 
 speaking of orphans, heiresses, age, poverty, maintenance of the 
 mother, &c.^^'; and it is a beautiful and praiseworthy feature in 
 the character of the Athenians, that this appeal was seldom made 
 in vain, but a part of the property was commonly transferred to 
 the wife or the children^^^ Upon the whole, the receipts actu- 
 ally obtained were in general far less than was expected, as is 
 shown by Lysias^ speech for the property of Aristophanes. If 
 
 ^8' Orat. c. Nicostrat. p. 1247, to. j ^^^ Instances of this may be seen in 
 rpia fJ.epr], a €k rSiV vofioiv rai lbia>Tr} Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 
 Ta> dnoypdyj/avTL ylyvcTai. 
 
 ■'^'^ Xenoph, Hellen. i. 7, 10, Ando- 
 cid. de Myst. p. 48, Decret. ap. Vit. 
 Dec. Orat. p. 226. 
 
 38-* C. Poliuch. p. 610. 
 
 ^8* Orat. c. Nicostrat. p. 1255. 
 
 386 Dcmcsth. c. Aphob. i. p. t<34, 6.
 
 396 
 
 THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES, 
 
 [bk. 1 
 
 there was any suspicion of concealment, this again furnished 
 material for fresh accusations. Tlius when Ergocles, the friend 
 of Thrasybulus, was deprived of his property by confiscation, 
 for having embezzled 30 talents of the pubUc money, and the 
 value of that found in his possession was inconsiderable, his 
 treasurer Epicrates was brought before the court, suspicions 
 being entertained that the property lay concealed in his house'"'. 
 
 Chapter XV. 
 
 The Tributes of the Allies, Origin of the Tributes^ and of the 
 subjection of the Athenian Allies. Amount of the Tributes 
 before the Anarchy (b. c. 404). 
 
 By far the most productive source of revenue belonging to the 
 Athenian state was the tributes {^opoi) of the allies, as the 
 ancients themselves were well aware^^^ They were, however, 
 an insecure and uncertain income, for the payments soon ceased 
 to be voluntary, and from the disturbances occasioned by war, 
 or the defection of the allies, were often irregularly made, or 
 even entirely failed^ ^^ 
 
 " Before the time of Aristides,^^ says Pausanias^®'*, " the 
 whole of Greece was free from tributes ;^^ by which statement 
 he wishes to detract from the fame of this person, by the men- 
 tion of the imposts with which he loaded the Grecian islands. 
 We question, in the first place, whether the name of Aristides 
 suffered by a work which at its first institution was honour- 
 able and just; and, in the second place, whether the payments 
 which Aristides introduced were entirely novel. At so early a 
 period as when Sparta had the precedence of all Greece, certain 
 monies {aTrocpopa) were paid for the uses of war, although we 
 have no accurate account of them. When the Athenians suc- 
 ceeded in the place of the Spartans, Aristides was commissioned 
 by the Greeks with the charge of investigating the territory 
 
 '■^"^ Lysias c. Ergocl. et c. Epicrat. 
 =«« Thucyd. i. )22, ii. 13, iii. 13, 
 91. 
 
 289 As was the case after the Sicilian 
 
 war. 
 
 39" viii. 52.
 
 CH. XV.] 
 
 THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. 
 
 397 
 
 and revenues of the different states, and of fixing, according to 
 the power of the several countries, the contribution which each 
 should make towards the equipment of the naval and miUtary 
 forces against the power of Persia. The moderation of Aris- 
 tides, the satisfaction expressed with his allotment, and also the 
 poverty in which he lived and died, have gained for him in all 
 ages the reputation of a just man'*'. The temple of Delos was 
 the treasury for the reception of these tributes ; and here also 
 the assemblies were held, to which all the aUies had admission ; 
 the Athenians only enjoyed the precedence together with the 
 administration of the money by means of the Hellenotamiee, 
 who were always Athenian citizens appointed by the government 
 of Athens. The contributions were, at their first institution in 
 Olymp. 'J'J, 3 (b. c. 470), known by the name oi tributes {(popocY^^, 
 and, according to the rate appointed by Aristides, amounted 
 to 460 talents a year^®^ ; and so early even as at that period it 
 had been determined which states were to supply money, and 
 which ships^^*. Everything was regulated by voluntary agree- 
 ment for a common object^"; for the preservation of their free- 
 dom, the small and weak states willingly annexed themselves to 
 the larger and more powerful. The ships of the allies assem- 
 bled at Athens, and those states which had ships gave to those 
 which had none^^^ And notwithstanding the payment of a 
 tribute the allies were independent {avrovofioty^'', as their share 
 in the regulation of the joint proceedings manifestly shows. 
 Gradually however they fell into entire subjection to the Athe- 
 nians, and were surrendered to their oppression and ill-treat- 
 ment; a mischance which was in truth frequently owing to their 
 
 39' Plutarch. Aristid. 24, Nepos 
 Aristid. 3, ^scliin. c. Ctesipli. p. 647, 
 Demosth. c. Aristocrat, p. 690, 1, 
 Diod. xi. 47, «Scc. 
 
 39* Thucyd. i. 96, Nepos Aristid. 3, 
 Diod. ubi sup. Dinarcli. c. Demosth. 
 The time is not Olymp. 75, 4, as Dio- 
 dorus states; see Dodwell's Annal. 
 Thucyd. under Olymp. 77, 5- 
 
 '■■^^ Thucyd. ubi sub. Plutarch. Aris- 
 tid. 34, Nepos ubi sup. Suidas in v. 
 
 'EWT]vora[xiai. Diodorus (ut sup.) has 
 incorrectly 560 talents, although in 
 xii. 40 he errs in the contrary direc- 
 tion, when he states the tributes in 
 time of Pericles at 460 talents. 
 
 ^^* Thucyd. ubi sup. 
 
 39* Besides the other passages see 
 Andocid. de Pace p. IO7. 
 
 39^ Andocid. ibid. 
 
 se7 Thucyd. i. 97.
 
 398 THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. [bK. III. 
 
 own conduct; for these states, in order to avoid serving in war, 
 agreed to supply money and vessels without the crews, but 
 frequently failed to pay their contributions ; and for this reason 
 they were ready to seize the first opportunity for revolt, although 
 their resistance would of necessity be unavailing, as they had 
 previously yielded up their power; nor had any sufficient pre- 
 parations been made against the Athenians, who were strength- 
 ened at their expense^^^ On the other hand, the Athenians, 
 although at first they were strict in their demands for crews and 
 vessels, favoured the inclination of the allies after the time of 
 Cimon, Avho willingly took empty ships and money from those 
 who would not serve in person. He allowed the allies to carry 
 on trade and agriculture without any disturbance, by which 
 means they became unfitted for war; and, on the other hand, 
 practised the Athenians, who w^ere maintained out of contri- 
 butions of the alHes, in naval exercises; for they were conti- 
 nually serving on board their vessels, and the arms were rarely 
 out of their hands^^^ Thus in the same degree that the military 
 strength of the allies declined, the Athenian power increased, 
 and with it a spirit of arrogance and severity towards the con- 
 federates*"". The payment of the tribute was now considered 
 as a duty of the allies, while they were at the same time deprived 
 of their vote in the assembly. The transfer of the treasury from 
 Delos to Athens placed the Athenian state in the unlimited 
 possession of these funds, and showed that the true relation 
 between the allies and Athens was that of tributary subjects to 
 their sovereign and protector. 
 
 From this period Athens made use of the resoxirces and 
 property of these allies for her own private interests, and against 
 their prosperity and freedom. The excuse alleged in favour of 
 this dangerous transfer of the treasure, was the greater security 
 against the barbarians ; and it is remarkable, that this allegation 
 proceeded from Samos, one of the allied states, although it was 
 doubtless made at the bidding of Pericles*" ^ Aristides declared 
 that the proceeding was expedient, but unjust, like the burning 
 
 388 Tlmcyd. i. 99. I '"" Cf, Diod. xi. 70. 
 
 399 Plutarch. Cini. I . | ^°' riutarch. Aristid. 25.
 
 CH. XV.] THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. 399 
 
 of the Grecian docks*"^: but as he had prevented the execution 
 of the latter project^ he could not have been zealous in his 
 endeavours to prevent the transfer of the treasure of Delos to 
 Athens, at least according to the judgment of Theophrastus ; 
 and he held the opinion, that in public affairs perfect justice 
 need not of necessity be followed"\ Pericles is stated to have 
 obtained the superintendence of the money that was brought 
 to Athens*'^*. He taught the Athenian people that they were not 
 accountable to the allies for these contributions, as the Athenians 
 waged war in their defence against the attacks of the barbarians, 
 while these states did not provide a horse, a ship, or a soldier; 
 that it was their duty to apply the money to objects which 
 would both promote their interests and enhance their celebrity; 
 and that by devoting their resources to the creation of works of 
 art, they would maintain every hand in employment, and at the 
 same time most splendidly adorn their city*°\ In fact, no 
 statesman ever applied the public revenue to nobler purposes 
 than Pericles, or conferred greater benefits upon commerce and 
 industry, which were especially promoted by the extended rela- 
 tions and increased naval force of Athens; but while he distri- 
 buted this money among the people, he built the wealth of 
 Athens upon maritime trade, and her ascendancy upon naval 
 power, omitting all concern for the welfare of the landholders, 
 whose property he gave up to devastation; and at the same 
 time he laid the foundation of the unlimited democracy, 
 which, as is evident from the diminution which he effected in 
 the power of the Areopagus, was unquestionably a part of his 
 policy, and to which even Aristides and Cimon, although in 
 their hearts they were aristocrats, essentially Contributed by 
 yielding to the spirit of the times. 
 
 After this transfer of the treasure, which (as near as can be 
 ascertained) took place about Olymp. 79, 4 (b.c. 461)'°', the 
 subjection of the allies was by degrees completely established. 
 
 --"2 Plutarch. Themist. 20, Aristid. '"'^ Plutarch. Pericl. 12, cf. Isocrat. 
 
 22, Cic. de Off. iii. 11. Su/x/xax- 29. 
 
 ^"3 Plutarch. Aristid. 25. i ''"° .Justin, iii. 6 ; see Dodwell Ann. 
 
 "o* Diod. xii. 38. i Thncyd. ad ann .
 
 400 
 
 THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 a point which we shall presently have occasion to notice. Not- 
 withstanding this arbitrary proceeding, Pericles does not appear 
 to have made any great alteration in the rate of the tributes; 
 for in his time they only amounted to about 600 talents"^ 
 The 140 talents, which is about the excess of this sum above 
 the rate fixed by Aristides, may be easily accounted for by the 
 acquisition of fresh allies subsequently to the time of Aristides, 
 particularly of the Asiatic states, and by the redemption of the 
 obligation to serve in war, or of the dependence of the free 
 states; to which the increase of the Euboean tribute, supposed 
 to have been the work of Pericles, probably refers. It is 
 expressly related of Alcibiades*°^, that he persuaded the Athe- 
 nians to make a new valuation in the place of that which had 
 been so equitably framed by Aristides, and being appointed for 
 this service together with nine colleagues, he imposed on an 
 average a double rate upon all the allies. This proceeding took 
 place in the beginning of the public career of Alcibiades, 
 shortly before the peace of Nicias concluded in Olymp. 89, 3 ; 
 for after this period the Athenians raised annually more than 
 1200 talents, that is, in fact, double the former amount""®: in 
 this compact, however, many states were suftered still to retain 
 the original assessment of Aristides. According to Plutarch"^% 
 the demagogues after the death of Pericles gradually increased 
 the tribute until it reached 1300 talents, not on account of the 
 expenses of war, but in order to defray the public distributions. 
 
 *°7 Thucyd. ii. 13, Plutarch. Aris- 
 tid. 24. Here Diodoriis (xii. 40) 
 falsely gives 460 talents. The passage 
 of Telecleides in Plutarch. Pericl. 16, 
 does not prove that Pericles had raised 
 or lowered the tributes, but only that 
 Le had the power of doing so. Cf. 
 ibid. 15, init. Concerning the Euboean 
 tributes see Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 214« 
 
 *^^ Andocid. c. Alcib. p. lie. npcorov 
 fjifv ovv ndo-as vfias tov <f)6pov rais 
 TToXeaiP 6^ ^PXl^ rd^ai, tuv vtt'' ^Apia- 
 Teidov ndvTcov ^iKaioTara rerayptuov, 
 alpeOeh cVi tovto) deKaros airos, pd- 
 Xiara binXaainv avrov (Ki'iuTOi rojj/ trvp- 
 
 pd^fjov enoirjaev, and on the same sub- 
 ject farther on. Cf. Aristid. Orat. 
 Plat. ii. 
 
 *°9 /Eschin. de Fals. Leg. p. 337, 
 Andoc. de Pace, p. 93. For the more 
 accurate determination of the time as 
 obtained from Aristophanes, see below, 
 chap. 19. In addition to what is there 
 said I may mention that the express 
 condition inserted in the ti-eaty of Ni- 
 cias, that certain cities should pay the 
 tribute at the rate fixed by Aristides, 
 distinctly shows that it had at that 
 time been increased. 
 
 *'° Aristid. 24.
 
 CH. XV.] THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. 401 
 
 the sacrifices, and other demands of a similar description; 
 whether this statement merely refers to Alcibiades and his col- 
 leagues, or to other public leaders, who lived at a later period 
 in the history of Athens, I do not attempt to determine. The 
 new arrangement of the tributes was however, according to the 
 account of Andocides, so oppressive, that many of the allies 
 left their native country, and emigrated to Thurii. 
 
 To any person who should wish to have an accurate know- 
 ledge of the respective means of the ancient nations, it would 
 be a matter of curiosity to know the amount paid by each indi- 
 vidual state; upon this point, however, the information which 
 we possess is most scanty. Cythera, after it had fallen under 
 the power of Athens (Olymp. 88, 4, B.C. 425), paid a tribute of 
 4 talents*' '. A greater number of data would be afforded us, if 
 more Athenian inscriptions upon the payments of the tributes 
 were extant. In a fragment, which probably is a part of a 
 catalogue of the tributaries, and of the sums which they had 
 paid or still owed*^% we find distinctly mentioned the Neopolitae 
 between Amphipolis and Abdera, the Thracian Peninsula, the 
 Limneeans of Sestos, and Tyrodiza in Thrace, which is rated at 
 1000 drachmas; also part of Mysia, probably the country along 
 the coast, is stated to have paid 10 talents; together with other 
 towns and countries whose names are either mutilated or 
 entirely lost, among which two items occur of 10 talents each, 
 two of 1 talent, one of 1000, another of 2000, and another of 
 3000 drachmas. 
 
 About the second year of the 91st Olympiad (b.c. 415) the 
 tributes were entirely abolished, and a transit duty of a twen- 
 tieth was introduced in their place, from an expectation that it 
 would produce a larger amount of revenue*'^; but of the amount 
 of the receipts obtained from this custom duty we are entirely 
 ignorant; unless the sum of 3000 talents, to which Plu- 
 
 411 
 
 Thucyd. iv. 57. i Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 143, where the 
 
 author refers this inscription to the re- 
 arrangement of the tributes by Alci- 
 biades. — Transl.] 
 *^^ See above, chap. 6. 
 
 *'^ In Chandler's Inscript. ii.23,p.53, 
 A wherever it occurs in this inscription 
 should be changed into A. The writing 
 is that which was in use before the ar- 
 chonship of Euclid (n.c. 403). [See i 
 
 2 D
 
 402 
 
 THE TRIBUTES OF THE ALLIES. [bK. Ill 
 
 tarch states that the demagogues finally succeeded in raising 
 the tribute, may be referred to it. This twentieth, as has 
 been already remarked, does not appear to have been aban- 
 doned until the battle of ^gospotamos put an end to the 
 tributary condition of the allies, in consequence of which the 
 board of hellenotamiee, which was manifestly created for the 
 administration of those monies, was suppressed*'*. As to the 
 conversion of these contributions into a custom duty, our 
 knowledge would also be more accurate, if the inscriptions 
 recording the event had been better preserved. A single 
 inscription*'', which probably refers to this point, is in so muti- 
 lated a state as to convey little information. 
 
 Chapter XVI. 
 
 Geneml Survey of the Athenian Allies before the Anarchy, 
 (B.C. 404.) 
 
 The obligation to pay a tribute to Athens was not, even in the 
 times which preceded the Anarchy, common without exception 
 to all the allied states, although with regard to this, as well as 
 
 ^'^ See book ii. ch. 7, and above, cli. 
 3, where the necessary information 
 with regard to the collection and ma- 
 nagement of the tributes will be found. 
 
 ^'* " Jam vero quum solum olim 
 Pocockii exemplum editum esset in 
 quo vs. I. est B02EITENEI, quod 
 in his hsec, Scocrft rr]v eiKo<TTT]v, la- 
 tere arbitrabar, (Ec. Civ. Ath. ii. 15, 
 conjeci decretimi hoc ad tributa in 
 vigesimam mutata pertinere : quae res 
 accidit circa Olymp. 91, 2 (vid. inf. 
 cap. 17): nunc melioribus exemplis 
 potitus antiquius id esse intelligo. [In 
 marmore legitur B0AENTENE2, i. e. 
 Boeckhio interprete BovXtjv ttjv e'xLs" 
 'Apet'ov ndyov, 2 pro X male Iecto.'\ Sed 
 quominus id ad priniitivam tributorum 
 institutionem Aristidis et Cimonis 
 aetate excogitatam referas, vel scrip- 
 iuriie forma impedit : nee qui id ipsum 
 
 voluit, quidquam demonstravit 
 
 Probabilius habeo hoc fragmentum ex 
 ea lege esse, qua tributa sociorum, Al- 
 cibiadis potissimum opera aucta, nova 
 ratione descripta et ordinata sint. Ea 
 res acta ante Olymp. 89, 3, ut conjicio 
 Olymp. 89, 1—2 (cap. 15, 19). Turn 
 etiam causas de tributis apud populum 
 vel in judiciis actas esse ex Antiphonte 
 docui (not. 467, 468, 470): tum rem 
 tributariam Atheniensibus maxime 
 cordi fuisse decent Aristophanis Ves- 
 pae Olymp. 89, 2, editae, ubi vs. 690, 
 memorantur homines eTraTreiXovvrfs 
 Kiiua^ocovTes' Adxrere rov <p6pov, rj 
 ^povrrjcras ttjv ttoXiv vfxcov dvarpeylroi. 
 Et vs. 727, niille urbes habes, at vvv 
 Tov (f)6pov jjplv dndyovaiv. Adde vs. 
 677-" Corp. Inscript. vol. i. p. 113, 
 No. 75.
 
 CH. XV I.J 
 
 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES. 
 
 403 
 
 other particulars, the circumstances of the Athenian alliance 
 were very various. 
 
 Many nations had only entered into agreements with x\thens 
 with respect to the military service, and provided mercenaries, 
 as for example the Arcadians, the Swiss among the Greeks, 
 and also the Acarnanians, and the Cretans; others were volun- 
 tarily connected with the Athenians for a certain time by 
 defensive or offensive alliances (eVtyLtap^/a or avfifiax^ajy either 
 from a preference for Athens, or for the sake of their own 
 interest, as was frequently the case with Argos, and in the 
 early part of the Peloponnesian war with Corcyra, Zacynthus, 
 the Messenians of Naupactus, and the Plataeans^'^. These 
 alliances expired after the conclusion of the period agreed upon, 
 in case they were not renewed, and were always unconnected 
 with any conditions for the payment of a tribute. 
 
 The nature of our inquiry limits us to the consideration of 
 the perpetual allies, who may be divided into independent 
 (auTovo/jLOL), and subject [viryjKoot). 
 
 The chief distinction between these two conditions was, that 
 the former class retained possession of unlimited jurisdiction, 
 whereas the subject allies were compelled to try all their dis- 
 putes in the courts of Athens. The nature of this compulsion 
 has not, however, been as yet satisfactorily ascertained. I 
 should in the first place remark that Casaubon*'', by the mis- 
 
 ^^« Cf. Thucyd. vi. 85, vii. 57. 
 
 "'7 Ad Athen. ix. p. 407, B. Kaff ov 
 be xpovou OaXaaaoKpaTOvvres ^Adrjvaioi 
 avrjyov els adrv ras vrjcrioiTiKcts Si'/cay. 
 ^AvTJyov does not mean traduxerunt, as 
 Casaubon translates it, but evocabant, 
 and the sense is, "At the time that 
 the Athenians decided {i.e. used to 
 decide) at Athens the law-suits of the 
 Islandei's." Concerning the expres- 
 sion dvdyeiv see Hudtwalker von den 
 Diateten, p. 123, although the passages 
 ■which he quotes are not entirely simi- 
 lar. This writer, however, who is so 
 well versed in the Athenian law, main- 
 tains in the same place that these suits 
 were called diKui utto avfi^oXcov, in a 
 
 sense different from the common ac- 
 ceptation. I have not however suc- 
 ceeded in finding any proof of his as- 
 sertion : Valesius ad Harpocrat., upon 
 whose authority he mainly depends, 
 (and who also quotes in p. 334, two 
 passages of Dion and Libanius, upon 
 the compulsory jurisdiction of the 
 Athenians, which I thought might be 
 passed over,) proves nothing in his 
 favour, nor in the other passages is 
 there anything which supports his opi- 
 nion, while the passage of Antiphon 
 de Herod. Caede p. 745, distinctly con- 
 tradicts it ; although even this testi- 
 mony is apparently opposed to the 
 words of Pollux viii. 63, dno avfx^o- 
 
 2 d'2
 
 404 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES [bK. ITI. 
 
 conception of a passage in Athenaeus, imagined that the Athe- 
 nian nesiarchs (although in fact no officers of this name ever 
 existed) originally decided the law- suits of the Islanders, and 
 that at a subsequent period when these offices ^yere abolished, 
 all litigations were carried on at Athens. It seems, on the con- 
 trary, that when the jurisdiction was taken away from the allied 
 states, it was immediately made compulsory upon them to refer 
 all disputes to the Athenian courts. The model of this regula- 
 tion, by which Athens obtained the most extensive influence 
 and an almost absolute dominion over the allies, was probably 
 found in other Grecian states which had subject confederates, 
 such as Thebes, Elis, and Argos. But on account of the re- 
 moteness of many countries, it is impossible that every trifle 
 could have been brought before the courts at xVthens; we must 
 therefore suppose that each subject state had an inferior juris- 
 diction of its owTi, and that the supreme jurisdiction alone be- 
 longed to Athens. Can it indeed be supposed that persons 
 would have travelled from Rhodes or Byzantium to Athens for 
 the sake of a law-suit for 50 or 100 drachmas? In private suits 
 a sum of money was probably fixed, above which the inferior 
 court of the allies had no jurisdiction: while cases relating to 
 higher sums w^ere referred to Athens; hence the amount of the 
 prytaneia, which were only paid in private causes^ ^^, was by this 
 interdiction of justice*'® augmented in favour of the Athenians. 
 The public and penal causes were however of far greater im- 
 portance to the Greeks from their being habituated to a free 
 government. There can be no doubt that cases of this descrip- 
 
 \(ov bi oT€ ol crv^fjLa^oi ediKa^ovro ; in j the Athenians by law-suits (dUai otto 
 this place howevei* the allies are doubt- (jv/m/SoXcoj/)." It is not here stated that 
 less meant to be independent and j the islanders would not when at home 
 equal with the Athenians. It were j have been able to can-y on diKat drro 
 much to be wished that some person ' a-vix^oXatv with Athenians, but only 
 would undertake a separate examina- that they preferred doing so in foreign 
 tion of the StKoi dno avfj-^oXcov. [This j countries, since there they could annoy 
 has been done by Schumann, Attische | the Athenians without fear or dan- 
 Trocess, p. 773 — 80, who however in- 
 terprets the passage of Antiphon thus : 
 " Many of the subject allies emigrate ' •»'» Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. i. IC. 
 to the main-land, dwell even among ; Compare above ch. 9, arf/n. 
 the enemies of Athens, and defraud i 
 
 ger." — Transl.] 
 *'^ Book iii. ch. 9.
 
 XVI.] 
 
 BEFORE THE AXAIICHY. 
 
 405 
 
 tion were to a great extent decided at Athens, and the few de- 
 finite statements which are extant refer to law-suits of this 
 nature. Thus Isocrates^*^ speaks of sentences of death passed 
 against the allies : the law-suit of Hegemon the Thasian, in the 
 age of Alcibiades, was evidently a public action**^; and the ora- 
 tion of Antiphon concerning the murder of Herodes is a defence 
 of a MytileneaUj who was proceeded against by a criminal pro- 
 secution subsequently to the revolt of his state, in consequence 
 of which defection it was made subject, and planted with cle- 
 ruchi. From the latter orator we learn that no subject state 
 had the right of condemning an accused person "without the 
 consent of the Athenians''^^ but that it had the power of com- 
 
 *■'' Paaath. 24. j 
 
 *^^ Of what description the law-suit i 
 of Hegemon of Thasos was (Chamse- ! 
 leon ap. Athen. ubi sup. ) is uncertain ; I 
 it may however be with some proba- | 
 biUty supposed to have been a biKr] \ 
 v^petos against the somewhat coarse ! 
 jokes of tlie parodist, which proceeded 
 as far as acts of violence ; for on one 
 occasion Hegemon even pennitted , 
 himself to throw stones from the stage 
 into the orchestra ; wlience it would I 
 have been easy to proceed to acts of 
 open >dolence. Concerning the Me- 
 troum, which occurs in this passage in 
 Athenteus, see Lives of the Ten Ora- ! 
 tors, p. 255, also Harpocration and 
 Valesius. It was there that the laws 
 were preserved ; it was in the vicinity 
 of the senate-house {^ovXevrrjpiov), 
 and there also the statues of the heroes 
 of the tribes ( eVwi/v/ioi) were placed, 
 upon which all new proposals of laws 
 were exposed for the information of 
 the public. Before any public action 
 could be brought on, it was also neces- 
 sary that it should be publicly exposed 
 in the same place. Demosth. c. Mid. 
 p. 548, nXrjv tv cKKeoiro npo tu>v enoovv- 
 fxcov. " EvKTTjpaiv Aov(Ti€vs iypay\raTO 
 Aripocrdevr) Uuiavica XnroTa^iov." Cf. 
 Herald. Animadv. vii. 16, 21. Now 
 in the Metroum, which was close at 
 hand, accusations were also drawn up, 
 
 and exposed to public view (Chamae- 
 leon ubi sup.), and this was the case 
 with the action against Hegemon the 
 parodist. Can it however be supposed 
 that private actions could have been 
 publicly exposed in this place ? None 
 but public actions were of sufficient 
 importance to make it necessary that 
 they should be communicated to the 
 people. Hence it is evident that the 
 action against Hegemon was a public 
 suit, and this may be seen from the 
 very words used by Chaniaeleon : ypa- 
 ylrdfievos ris nai tov 'HyrjfjLOva diKijVf 
 OTTov Toiv 8iKa>v TjCTav al ypa<pa\, tov rrjv 
 dUrjv ypayjrapevov : at least ypd(f>€aBai 
 is very rarely used of a private action, 
 as in Isocrat. adv. CaUimach. 5. [It 
 appears from the passage in Athenseus 
 that some person had compelled Hege- 
 mon of Thasos to go to Athens, for 
 the purpose of referring to the Athe- 
 nian courts an offence committed in 
 his own country, ypayj/dfievos ris tov 
 'Hyrjpova vlktjv rjyayev els Tag ^AOrjvas. 
 Hegemon had also on some occasion 
 thrown stones from the stage into the 
 orchestra, probably in the theatre at 
 Athens. There does not therefore ap- 
 pear to be much giound for the con- 
 jecture advanced in the beginning of 
 this note. — Transl.] 
 
 ■•2^ P. 724, 6 ovde TToXei (a subject 
 state such as ^M} tiloue) e^eaTiv avev
 
 406 
 
 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES [bK. li; 
 
 mencing the investigation^" (an arrangement which was indis- 
 pensably necessary), and the Athenian court only gave judg- 
 ment. For more determinate accounts on this point I have in 
 vain sought. 
 
 The independent allies must have had the power of de- 
 ciding for themselves with regard to war and peace, and at 
 least a formal share in all decrees, although the preponderance 
 of Athens deprived the latter right of its force; while the sub- 
 ject states were, according to the legal conditions, governed by 
 the will of the Athenians. Both had their own public officers; 
 for that this was the case with the subject states is proved by 
 the Delian archons who occur in the 100th Olympiad (b.c. 
 380), at a time when Delos was so far in the power of Athens, 
 that the latter state was in possession of the temple, which it 
 managed by its own amphictyons. Nevertheless we find that 
 Athens sometimes appointed archons or governors of its own in 
 the states of the subject allies. These officers may be com- 
 pared with the harmosts of the Spartans^^\ Thus Polystratus, 
 
 'A67]vai(ov ovbeva Bavarcd ^rjfiLaxrai. It 
 should be observed, that the person who 
 delivers this speech is not an Athenian, 
 as might be supposed from the Greek 
 argument, but a foreigner; he is in- 
 deed one of the ancient inhabitants of 
 Mytilene, which is shown by the ac- 
 count of his father (p. 742—746), who 
 was in Mytilene at the time of the re- 
 volt, and afterwards went to JEnus ; 
 but he had perhaps formerly lived at 
 Athens as a foreigner, and part of his 
 property and his children were there 
 at the time of the revolt (p. 743). 
 His son Helus (p. 713) includes him- 
 self among the foreigners, and (p. 
 737) he calls Ephialtes t6u Ifxcrepov 
 TToXirrjv: also in p. 739, oi 'EXKijvora- 
 fiiai ol vixerepoi. [And Bekker Orat, 
 Att. tom. i. p. 72, has restored rj vfie- 
 repa noXis from 3 MSS.] Reiske, by 
 supposing that Antiphon's client was 
 an Athenian, has fallen into error 
 throughout the whole speech. Hence 
 he misunderstands the passage in p. 
 
 743, and writes iKava yap rjv to. iv€)(ypa, 
 
 a €"x^T€ aVTOV, 01 T€ TToideS Koi TO. XP1~ 
 
 para, without making any mention of 
 this alteration beneath the text. The 
 reason given in p. 865 of his notes is 
 however quite futile, and the old read- 
 ing et;^€ro must be restored, according 
 to which the children and property of 
 the father of Antiphon's client were 
 not in Athens, as according to Reiske's 
 emendation, but, what was more natu- 
 ral, in Mytilene. 
 
 ^^3 This is evident from the same 
 speech of Antiphon, p. 719 sqq. as the 
 examination and the torturing, and in- 
 deed the whole investigation, had been 
 previously gone through at Mytilene. 
 
 *'^* Harpocration ; fTria-KOTrof 'Av- 
 Ti(f)a)V iv T(o Trepl tov Aivdicov (popov, 
 KOL iv Ttc Kara Aaia-novbiov ol Trap' 
 ^A6r)vaicov els Tcis vnyjKoovs rroXeis eTTicr- 
 K€-^aadai ra nctp eKaarois neprropevoi, 
 (TTlCTKOTrOl KOL (fivXtiKes eKoXovvTOj ovs ol 
 AcLKcoves appocTTcis eXeyov. OeocPpaa- 
 Tos yovv eV tt/jcoto) tuiv noXiriKau twv
 
 CH. XVI.] 
 
 BEFORE THE ANARCHY. 
 
 407 
 
 one of the 400, had been an archon at Oropus*^"*; we hear of 
 similar officers even before the Peloponnesian war in the sub- 
 ject Samos*^% and one as late as at the time of ^schines in the 
 island of Andros*^^, which had indeed been formerly settled l)y 
 Athenian colonists, and perhaps may be thought to have been 
 under an Athenian governor for that reason. Also in time of 
 war they had Athenian commanders in the cities, together with 
 garrisons, if there appeared to be any necessity. Of those 
 archons or governors we know by name, the episcopi, of whom 
 I have already treated, and the officers called KpvTrrol, who 
 transacted some foreign affairs in secret, but of what nature, 
 we are not informed^^^ It cannot be proved that there ever 
 were Athenian officers of this kind in the independent states, 
 except only that their military forces were commanded by an 
 Athenian general"". Both classes of the allied states had un- 
 questionably the unrestricted administration of their home 
 affairs, and the power of passing decrees. The subject states 
 were necessarily in this point limited to a narrow circle; it is, 
 however, wholly inconceivable that every decree which they 
 passed required a ratification from Athens or the Athenian 
 authorities"*^". 
 
 The obligation to pay a tribute was held originally not to 
 
 npos Kuipovs (prjcTLV ovtco' IloWa yap 
 KoXXiov Kara ye rrjv tov ovofxaros OeaiVi 
 ois ol Aa.K(i>ves app-ocTTas (f)d(TK0VT€s els 
 ras TToXeis 7re/x7reii/, ovk cniaKonovs ovSe 
 (f)v\aKaSy as * Adijvaioi. The term cf)v\a^ 
 is applied in Thucyd. iv. 104, to the 
 Athenian commander at Amphipolis. 
 
 *^^ Lysias pro Polystr. p. 569. 
 
 ^2« Thucyd. i. 115. 
 
 ''27 ^schin. c. Timarch. p. 127. It 
 is to archons of this description that 
 the fragment of a law in Aristoph. 
 Av. 1049, refers, iav de ris e^eXavvrj 
 Tovs ap^oin-aSj Kal fxr) de^Tjrai Kara rrjv 
 arrjXrjv. 
 
 *^ Lex. Seg. p. 273. Kpynrr] : 
 dpx'T) Tis vnb TUiV 'Adrjvaicov Trepiropevrj 
 els TOVS vTT-qKoovs, tva Kpv(})a eVireXe- 
 crtocri ret e^o) yiv6p.eva. dia tovto yap 
 
 Kal KpVTTTol €KKr)dT]CraV. 
 
 *^^ As the instance of Chios shows, 
 Thucyd. viii. 9. 
 
 ^3<^ This must not be inferred from 
 the Delian decree in Corp. Inscript. 
 Gr. No. 2270. For although it is not 
 of the time when Delos was under the 
 rule of Hadrian, it is of late date, when 
 Delos was no longer a separate com- 
 munity, but had been incorporated 
 with Athens (whence the expression 
 6 drjfxos t5)v ^A0r]vaia)v ev A17X0)), and 
 was under the protection of Rome. 
 Moreover the application that is made 
 in it by the Deliahs for the ratification 
 of the decree by the Athenian senate 
 and people is voluntary, and not com- 
 pulsory. [See the author's notes to 
 this inscription iii his edition. — -. 
 Transl.]
 
 408 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES [bK. III. 
 
 be incompatible with independence^ nor indeed in later times 
 was it the absolute criterion of dependence or subjection ; but 
 the independent allies of the Athenians were commonly free 
 from tribute, and were only bound to provide ships and their 
 crews {ovx vrroreXels (popov, vav<i Be Trapep^ovre? : vaval Kal ov 
 <f)6pa) virrjKooi'. veojv Trapo^^fj avTovofioi); while the subject allies 
 paid a tribute (vTroreXety, (f^opov uTroreXe^^)"^; although the 
 latter were sometimes, in spite of their tribute, also compelled 
 to serve either in the fleet or by land. Independence, together 
 with an obligation to pay a tribute to Athens, and without any 
 alliance with the Athenians, was granted in the peace of Nicias, 
 in Olymp. 89, 3 (b.c. 422), to the cities of Argilus, Stageirus, 
 Acanthus, Scolus, Olynthus, and Spartolus, and the Athenians 
 were only empowered to induce them to an alliance upon their 
 own voluntary agreement. This qualified dependence, which 
 was also extended to some other cities*^% was a perfect model 
 of the original form of the Athenian confederacy. If these 
 cities became allies of Athens, they were in that case inde- 
 pendent, and yet tributary, although exempt from military ser- 
 vice ; which was the precise condition of those states which 
 contributed money in the time of Aristides. 
 
 It should be also observed, that the difference of these con- 
 ditions did not arise at successive periods of time: those states 
 were subject which had either originally offered to pay a tribute 
 instead of the obligation to serve in war, or had subsequently 
 commuted their quota of troops and ships for a tribute, or had 
 been conquered in using their forces in opposition to Athens. 
 Those alone remained independent, without paying any tribute, 
 to whom one of these three cases did not apply. Those 
 states were independent, and at the same time liable to the 
 payment of a tribute, which had before paid tribute and been 
 subject, but had obtained their independence by a particular 
 agreement between Sparta and Athens, without the Athenians 
 being forced to take off the tribute which had been before 
 received. Nor can it be fairly said that the Athenians had no 
 excuse for exacting a tribute from those who did not perform 
 
 Thucyd. vii. 57, ii. 0, vi. 85. *''^ Thucyd. v. 18.
 
 ClI. XVlc] BEFORE THE ANARCHY. 409 
 
 any military service, and also for depriving them of jurisdiction; 
 for the tribute they paid out of what Athens had maintained or 
 procured for them"% and of the latter privilege they were 
 unworthy, if they refused to bear arms. 
 
 It is however an unquestionable stain in the character of the 
 Athenians, that they gradually reduced many independent states 
 to dependence, although the alliance would have been much 
 sooner dissolved without this exertion of power. We should also 
 remark, that independence is simply called freedom {eXevOepla), 
 and subjection servitude [hovXelaY^*, which last must not be 
 considered as identical with the conversion of the inhabitants 
 into slaves [ayhpairohtafjios)', the cases in which the situation of 
 servitude would be particularly mentioned, are when the citizens 
 were not only deprived of independence, but when their pro- 
 perty was also taken from them, and given to new colonists, to 
 whom the ancient inhabitants, if they did not emigrate, stood in 
 the relation of renters of their former lands ; a state not much 
 superior to the condition of the Helots or the Penestee. 
 
 At the breaking out of the Peloponnesian war there were 
 only three allied states of Athens which still preserved their 
 independence, viz., Chios, Mytilene in the island of Lesbos, 
 and Methymna*^^ Many others, which had formerly been 
 independent, such as Thasos and Samos, had lost their fleets 
 and their liberty. The first state which was reduced to a con- 
 dition of servitude was Naxos, in consequence of its revolt, 
 although it is probable that up to that period this island had 
 paid no tribute, but had only furnished vessels, as it did at the 
 battle of Salamis"^^. The other Cvclades were then reduced to 
 
 *^^ Isocrat. Panatli. 25. i dependence, the Naxians being com- 
 
 ■'s* Thucyd. ii. 10, v. 9, 92, vi. 76,77, ! pelled to pay tribute, and also losing 
 
 80, Isocrat. Su/Lt/iax- 16, Diod. xv. 19, 
 and elsewhere frequently. Cf. Xenopli. 
 de Rep Ath. 1, 18. 
 
 ^^ Thucyd. ii. 9, iii. 10, vi. 85, cf. 
 vii. 57. 
 
 436 Herod, viii. 46. Concerning the 
 subjection of this island Thucydides 
 
 their independence, -which till then 
 had been unheard of. Thucydides in- 
 tentionally makes use of the expression 
 edovXoidr) to distinguish from the pre- 
 ceding word avhpatTob'KTai. It is pos- 
 sible that cleruchi had been already 
 sent as a garrison to Naxos, to Avhom 
 
 says (i. 98), ibovKoaOr) Trapa to Kude- j the inhabitants stood in the relation of 
 arrjKoy; by which I conceive that he [ tenants to landlords, 
 does not mean slavery, but comj^lote |
 
 410 
 
 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES [bK. Ill, 
 
 the same condition, with the exception of the Spartan Melos, 
 and Thera, which was included by some among the Cyclades^^^. 
 The centre of these islands was the sacred Delos, which was 
 considered holy by all the Greeks, on account of ancient religious 
 worship, and had once been the seat of an Amphictyonic confe- 
 deracy. The Athenians appear to have laid claims to this 
 island, or at least to the temple, in very early times ; for Ery- 
 sichthon, the son of Cecrops*^% is reported to have gone thither 
 for the sake of some religious ceremonies, and Pisistratus made 
 a purification of the island*^^ The possession of it was doubt- 
 less of the first importance to the Athenians, so soon as they 
 aimed at obtaining the ascendancy of Greece, for which object 
 religion was a powerful auxiliary. Athens also persuaded some 
 prophets of Delos to foretel that she would once possess the 
 dominion of the sea''". In Olymp. 88, 3 (b.c. 426), the Athe- 
 nians took entire possession of the temple, made frequent puri- 
 fications of the island; and in Olymp. 89, 3 (b.c. 422), expelled 
 the ancient inhabitants upon the pretext of impurity, and 
 settled the island with Athenians, as the Delians were sus- 
 pected of being favourable to Sparta ; but Athens was subse- 
 quently compelled to reinstate them at the command of the 
 oracle' '^ 
 
 In order to weaken the influence upon the minds of the 
 Greeks, which the possession of this temple had or might have 
 given to the Athenians, it would manifestly have been expedient 
 for the Spartans to deprive them of it : and we can only attri- 
 bute it to a want of political foresight that Pausanias, the son 
 of Pleistoanax, king of Lacedsemon, while he held Athens in a 
 state of blockade, should have given a scornful and contemp- 
 tuous refusal to the petition of the Delians for the recovery of 
 their temple"^ The Athenians therefore remained in undis- 
 turbed possession, which they had not lost in the 107th or 
 
 ^27 Thucyd. ii. 9. 
 
 *-« Pausan. i. 18—31, Plianodem. 
 ap. A then. ix. p. 392 D. 
 
 ^39 Ilerod. i. C4.' 
 
 ^^^ Semus Delias ap. At lieu. viii. 
 p. 331 F. 
 
 *^' Thiic. i. n, iii. 104, v. 1, viii. 108, 
 V. 32, Pausan. iv. 27, Diod. xii. 73. 
 
 **'^ Plutarch. Apophthegm. Lacon. 
 witli the emendation of Dorville de 
 Delo Miscell. Observ. vol. vii. part i.
 
 CH. XVI.J 
 
 BEFORE THE ANARCHY 
 
 411 
 
 108th Olympiad (b.c. 352-45), when the Dehans, in the 
 Amphictyonic council of Pylae, endeavoured to assert their 
 rights against Athens, whose defence was conducted by Hype- 
 rides as advocate {ctvvSlkos) in the famous DeHan oration, and 
 which he mainly rested upon arguments derived from the 
 fabulous history of the island''*\ 
 
 Besides this insular group, all the other islands belonged 
 to the subject allies, which are included in a line running 
 from Byzantium along the coast of Europe as far as Cythera, 
 near the promontory Malea, and from thence northwards from 
 Crete over Carpathos and Rhodes as far as Doris, and pro- 
 ceeding northwards from thence along the coast of Asia to 
 Chalcedon*", except the independent states mentioned above, 
 and the islands belonging to Lacedaemon, of which Cythera first 
 came into the power of Athens in Olymp. 88, 4 (b.c. 425), and 
 Melos in Olymp. 91, 1 (b.c. 416), after an obstinate defence"". 
 Many were distinguished of old for their power and wealth, 
 such as Paros*"*^ in the Cyclades, Thasos abounding in metals, 
 the flourishing and powerful Samos"*^, the inhabitants of w^hich 
 received their independence after the defeat in Sicily''"; also 
 Rhodes and ^Egina, which was made tributary in Olymp. 80, f 
 (b.c. 458)"*% and Euboea, whose five chief cities, Chalcis, Ere- 
 tria, Car)'stus, Styra, and Histieea, afterwards Oreus, were all 
 under the dominion of Athens"*", were in part colonized with 
 Athenians. Now although the smaller islands were unim- 
 portant w^hen considered singly, their united resources amounted 
 to a considerable power, if we reckon all those which lie within 
 the circumference above-mentioned, as far as the distant islands 
 of Carpathos, Casos, and Chalce"", which were included among 
 the allies. 
 
 ***' Demosth. de Corona, Vit. Dec. 
 Orat, in iEschiu. Apollon. in Vit. 
 ^schin. Schol. Ilermog. p. 389. 
 
 *** This is the substance of the dif- 
 ferent accounts given by Thucydides 
 in tlie passages ah-eady quoted. 
 
 <** Concerning the former see Thuc. 
 iv. 54, cf. vii. 57- 
 
 **^ Herod, vi. 132, Nepos Miltiad. 
 vii. Steph. Byzant. from Ephorus. 
 
 ^^7 Thucyd. viii. 73, 76. This island 
 once sent GO vessels against Darius 
 the son of Hystaspes, the Chiaus 100, 
 the Lesbians 60, Herod, vi. 8. 
 
 ^^8 Thucyd. viii. 21. 
 
 ^^9 Diod. xi. 75, Thuc. i. 108. 
 
 ^=» Thucyd. \d. 76, 80, vii. 67- 
 
 ^51 Concerning the two latter see 
 Schol. Thucyd. ii. 0.
 
 412 
 
 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES 
 
 [bk. 1 
 
 Among the subject states Thucydides also enumerates the 
 coast of Caria, the Dorians who bordered upon the Carians, 
 Ionia, the Hellespont, and the Grecian territory in Thrace*^% 
 which includes powerful and famous cities, such as Halicar- 
 nassus, Cnidos, Miletus, which had once sent out 80 vessels 
 against Darius*", and furnished infantry to the Athenians^"; 
 Ephesus, Colophon, celebrated for its equestrian forces, Teos, 
 Priene, Erythrge, Smyrna, and the other Ionian cities. Ionia 
 upon the whole produced a very considerable revenue to the 
 Athenians**^ To these may be added Antandros, Abydos, 
 Sigeum, Lampsacus, Priapus, Parium, Cyzicus"% together with 
 Proconnesus, Chalcedon, Byzantium*", Selymbria, Perinthus, 
 Sestos, and the Thracian peninsula, the whole southern coast of 
 Thrace, the coast of Macedonia with its projecting capes and 
 promontories, where the important cities of Amphipolis, Olyn- 
 thus. Acanthus, Stageirus, Menda, Scione, and Potideea"^^, were 
 situated ; the first of which towns was of the greatest moment 
 to the Athenians on account of the revenues which they derived 
 from it, and the large supplies of wood for ship-building which 
 it furnished*^®; Macedonia is also mentioned in orations of a 
 late date as having formerly paid a tribute**'". Lastly, Oropus 
 in Boeotia was also included among the tributary places*^', and 
 for a time Nissea in Megaris and Minoa. 
 
 Now although Athens even in the time of its greatest power 
 could not have been always secure of each one of these many 
 states, it is yet easily perceived that so large a number of sub- 
 jects laid the foundation of no inconsiderable power; and 
 although Jason is represented by Xenophon*^^ as speaking con- 
 temptuously of the small islands which paid tribute to Athens, 
 
 "2 Time. ii. 9, cf. vi. 77- 
 
 <^3 Herod, vi. 8. 
 
 *^* Time. iv. 54. 
 
 ^" Time. iii. 31. 
 
 "® Coneerning the latter see Time, 
 viii. 107, Diod. xiii. 40. 
 
 ^-■^^ For the latter see Thucyd. i. 
 117, Xenoph. Anab. vii. 1, 27, &c. 
 
 *^^ Concerning the tributary state 
 of tbis town there is a clear pjissage in 
 
 Thuc. i. 56, before the'revolt. 
 
 *^^ Thuc. iv. 108. Concerning the 
 Clialeidian cities see also Thuc. i. 67, 
 58, where the Bottiaeans are still men- 
 tioned. 
 
 '•^" Orat. de Ilalones. p. 70, 20, and 
 thence in the spurious 5th Philippic, 
 p. 15G, 17. 
 
 '«' Thuc. ii. 23. 
 
 '"' llellen. vi. 1. 4.
 
 cn. XVI.] 
 
 BEFORE THE ANARCHY, 
 
 413 
 
 it is not true that this charge of insignificance can justly be 
 applied to earlier times. Aristophanes in the comedy of the 
 Wasps'" (Olymp. 89, 2, B.C. 423), reckons 1000 tributary cities, 
 and founds upon this computation a ludicrous proposal for the 
 maintenance of the Athenian citizens, viz. that each city 
 should be required to maintain 20 Athenians; a sufficient proof 
 that 1000 cannot here mean merely a large number, as the 
 Grecian Scholiast says in the beginning of his note. No one 
 indeed would suppose that this was the precise number of the 
 tributary cities, but it cannot have been far distant from the real 
 amount, for a gross exaggeration would have been merely absurd. 
 It would also be easy to enumerate some hundred cities, 
 although we are ignorant of far the larger number. 
 
 It should indeed be remarked, that many small cities did not 
 each pay a separate tribute, but sent it to Athens in one sum, 
 and these Aristophanes probably reckons individually. Many 
 small islands had several cities, which paid tribute either toge- 
 ther or separately. Thus Icaros contained three*", and Ceos 
 four, tributary cities'". That several states paid in their con- 
 tributions under one account, which they probably divided 
 among themselves without any interference on the part of 
 Athens, maybe perceived from an inscription already quoted'®^; 
 and if any increase was made in the amount of the tribute, it 
 was natural that those cities which had previously been united 
 should then be divided. The grammarians quote two speeches 
 of Antiphon, the one concerning the tribute of the Lindians'", 
 the other concerning the tribute of Samothrace"^^. Antiphon was 
 an opponent of Alcibiades, against whom he delivered an ora- 
 tion, and whose recal during the government of the 400 he 
 endeavoured to prevent. Hence it may be conjectured that 
 these orations were directed against the increase of the tribute 
 
 4«3 Vs. 795. 
 
 *°* See the notes to Corp. Inscript. 
 Gr. No. 158. 
 
 ■"^^ Swidas in v. BaKxvXiBrjs. 
 
 ^^^ See note 590. 
 
 '»*'7 Harpocrat. in v. cVio-KOTrot, and' 
 TTfiJ', arra, eTrayyeXia, npo(T(f)opa, avvr]- 
 
 yopoiy TpLJBciivevofxevoi, 'A/Lt(/)i7roXtff, 
 where AINAI12N should be written 
 with Valesius for AHNAIflN. 
 
 ^68 Harpocrat. and Suid. in v. cino- 
 ra^is, Harpocrat. in vv. e/cXoyetf, act, 
 aTTodidofxevoi, (rvvreXety, Suid. in v. 
 ^afxoBpaKJj.
 
 414 GENERAL SURVEY OF THE ALLIES. [bK. III. 
 
 made by Alcibiades; for the allies being discontented and 
 oppressed may have applied to Antiphon as an enemy of Alci- 
 biades. These speeches appear to have chiefly referred to the 
 separation of several states^ which had been previously united. 
 Rhodes had paid tribute for a long period'^®; but perhaps 
 Lindus, lalysus^ and Cameirus, made their payments jointly 
 before the new arrangement of Alcibiades, and were then sepa- 
 rated for the first time. This supposition may be proved more 
 distinctly with regard to the oration concerning the tribute of 
 Samothrace. A fragment of it still extant shows that Antiphon 
 did not compose this speech in his own person, but that the 
 Samothracians themselves were the speakers, who gave an account 
 of the history of their island*^" : they are in this passage speaking 
 against some burthen which was imposed upon them, as indeed 
 is evident even from the name of the oration. Now in the same 
 speech mention was made of those who paid the tribute toge- 
 ther {avvreXelsy^^, and also of their separation, by which they 
 were compelled to pay singly {awora^Lsy^'^ ; and it was doubt- 
 less of this change and the accompanying increase of the tribute 
 that they complained. 
 
 If any one should suppose that a tribute of 1200 or 1300 
 talents could not have been oppressive with so large a number 
 of cities as Aristophanes states; it must on the other hand be 
 observed that these cities had also to defray their own expenses, 
 that for a length of time large sums of money went out of the 
 country and never returned, and that at the time of the Pelopon- 
 
 ^«^ Thucyd. vii. 57. ! Seg. p. 305, 9, Eustathius and Schol. 
 
 ■*7*' It is singular that no one has 
 perceived that the passage in Suidas 
 in V. I^afiodpaKT] is a fragment of Anti- 
 
 Villois. ad II. N. 13, Q. 78. 
 
 *^' Harpocrat. ^vvreXeTs- ol cruvda- 
 7rav(ovT€S Koi crvpeiacPepovTes' to 6e 
 
 phon : Koi yap ol ttjv dpxrjv oUrjcravres ' npayp.a avvreXeLa KoXelrai, coy eariu 
 (I. olKicravT€s) ttjv vrjcrov rjaav "Sap-Lor cvpiiv iv r<a ^AvTi(f)a>irros nepl rou 2a- 
 
 €^ 6)1/ f]p.€is iy€v6p.e6a' KaTtoKicrdTjaav 
 de dvdyKT]^ ovk inidvp-ia ttJ9 vrjcrov. 
 'E^eTTecrov yap vtto Tvpdvvtov ex 2a/xov, 
 Ka\ TVXT] f^prjaavTO ravrr], koi Xeiav 
 \a^6vT€S dno rrjs QpaKrjs dcfuKPOvvrai 
 
 p.o6paK<ov <p6pov. 
 
 •*7=^ Harpocrat. (Suidas, Zonaras,) 
 'ATTorn^tf TO X^P*-^ TeTd^Oai tovs npo- 
 Tcpov dXKrjXoLS avvT€Tayfj.€vovs fls to 
 vnoTcXelv tov icpt(Tp.^vov cf)6pov. 'Aj/- 
 
 tV Tr)P vrjo-ov. With regard to the j rtcficop iv roi n(p\ tov ^afioOpaKcov 
 history comp. Ileraclid. Fragment xxi. <p6pov. 
 ed. Kohler, and Pausan. vii. 4, Lex. I
 
 CH. XVII.] THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS. 415 
 
 nesian war, the quantity of coin circulating in Greece was incon- 
 siderable. Two centuries and a half afterwards, Athens would 
 have demanded much higher sums, for Rhodes alone derived a 
 revenue of 120 talents a year from Caunus and Stratonicea^". 
 
 Chapter XVII. 
 
 The Tributes and Allies of Athens after the Anarchy (b.c. 404). 
 
 Although the defeat at ^gospotamos had deprived the Athe- 
 nians of all their allies, even of the islands of Lemnos, Imbros, 
 and Scyros*^% they yet continued gradually to acquire fresh con- 
 federates; for ten years afterwards (Olymp. 96, 2, b.c. 395), 
 the alliance between Athens, Boeotia, Corinth, and Argos, 
 excited the alUes of Sparta, particularly Euboea and the Chalci- 
 deans in Thrace, to revolt; Conon's victory at Cnidos procured 
 them Samos, Methone, Pydna, and Potideea, together with 
 twenty other cities, including Cos, Nisyros, Teos, Chios, 
 Ephesus, Mytilene, and Erythrae : Diodorus also mentions the 
 Cyclades in general, and even the island of Cythera'"'^; the con- 
 quest of the whole of Lesbos is ascribed to Thrasybulus: this 
 general also reestablished the power of Athens in the Helles- 
 pont, and restored the transit-duties at Byzantium (Olymp. 
 97, 1, B. c. 392); the greatest part of the Grecian coast of Asia, 
 most of the islands, and even Rhodes, distant as it was, were 
 subjected to the dominion of Athens. 
 
 Now, although we have not any accurate information con- 
 cerning the state of the Athenian allies at this period, there can 
 exist but little doubt that the ancient arrangements were for the 
 most part renewed, and that they again became tributary and 
 dependent. Athens exercised its naval dominion anew, and the 
 whole of Greece came under the power of the Athenians, as was 
 subsequently the case after the campaigns of Timotheus^'^; but 
 the disastrous peace of Antalcidas (Olymp. 98,2, b.c. 387) only 
 
 473 poiyb. xxxi. 7, 12. 
 
 "74 Andoc. de Pace, p. 96. 
 
 *''^ Dinarch. c. Demosth. p. 
 
 n, 
 
 Diod. in Olymp. m, 2, and liis com- 
 mentators. 
 
 ^'•^ Isocrat. Areopag. 5.
 
 416 THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS [bK. III. 
 
 left the Athenians their own ancient islands of Lemnos, Imbros, 
 and Scyros; Asia Minor, including Clazomenge and Cyprus, 
 fell into the hands of Persia; all the other cities and islands 
 became independent^". The Chersonese even and the colonies 
 did not remain in the power of Athens; the landed property in 
 foreign countries belonging to her citizens and even their claims 
 for debt were lost^^^. The Spartans indeed soon violated this 
 treaty, but more to their own advantage than to that of the 
 Athenians ; for the Grecians still sided with Sparta. It was 
 not until after Olymp. 100, 3 (b.c. S/S), that the Athenians by 
 means of a fortunate combination of events, and a prudent and 
 disinterested policy, were enabled for a time to re-establish 
 their power ; of which however it would be inconsistent with 
 my object to give more than a short account : for an accurate 
 enumeration of all the facts connected with the Athenian 
 confederacy, could only be expected from a detailed history of 
 Greece. 
 
 Athens having in the above-mentioned year, in the archon- 
 ship of Nausinicus, made the noblest exertions in order to sup- 
 port Thebes against the power of Sparta, and to liberate the 
 Cadmea from its foreign garrison, and the plans of the Spartans 
 having miscarried; in Olymp. 100, f (b.c. 377)^ Byzantium, 
 Chios, Mytilene, and Rhodes, revolted to Athens'''^ and a new 
 confederacy was formed, which gradually obtained fresh mem- 
 bers. The whole of Euboea, with the exception of Histiaea, 
 which remained true to the Spartans, came over to the Athe- 
 nians^^'; Chabrias subdued Peparethos, Sciathos, and other 
 small islands^^'; the sea-fight of Naxos, which was gained by 
 the same general (Olymp. 100, 4, b.c. 377)^ decided the maritime 
 supremacy of Athens, while the Spartans were at the same time 
 unsuccessful by land^°*. The Athenians soon reestablished 
 themselves more firmly in Thrace, after the taking of Abdera; 
 although the powerful state of Olynthus belonged to Lacedse- 
 
 ^77 Xenoph. HeUen. v. 1, 28, Diod. "«" Diod. xv. 30. 
 
 xiv. 110, Isocrat. Sv^/xa;^. 22. Cf. 
 Andoc. de Pace pp. 95, 96. 
 
 ■'7« Andoc. de Pace p. 96, cf. p. 107. 
 
 ^'9 Diod. XV. 28. 
 
 ^' Diod. ibid. 
 
 *^* Diod. XV. 35, and his commen- 
 tators.
 
 CH. XVII.] AFTER THE ANARCHY. 41/ 
 
 mon; and to the west their power extended as far as Corcyra; 
 the peace concluded between the states of Greece in Olymp, 
 101, 2 (B.C. 375), through the mediation of Artaxerxes, by 
 which the independence of all the alhes was again ensured, 
 remained inoperative. The Spartans, even after the taking of 
 Corcyra and the victory of Timotheus at Leucas, ceded to the 
 Athenians the entire ascendancy {rjye/juovLo) by sea. The peace 
 of Olymp. 102, 2 (b.c. 371), together with the subsequent battle 
 of Leuctra, shattered still more the strength of the Spartans; 
 and in Olymp. 102, 4 (b.c. 369), they yielded to the Athenians 
 an equal share in the sovereignty by sea and land^®\ The 
 taking of Torone and Potidaea, which ensued in Olymp. 104, 1 
 (b.c. 364)^% gave to Athens a great preponderance in Thrace. 
 Thus the power of Athens again extended from the Thracian 
 Bosporus to Rhodes, and from thence over the islands and 
 some of the maritime cities upon the main land. 
 
 The merit of having so greatly raised and benefitted their 
 country chiefly belongs to the generals, Chabrias, Iphicrates, 
 Timotheus the son of Conon, and the orator Callistratus. 
 Timotheus in particular obtained great celebrity both by his 
 military conduct and by his dexterity in acquiring allies^^^; for 
 he even added the Epirots, the Acarnanians, and the Chaonians, 
 although these nations were doubtless under no obligation to 
 pay a tribute^^^; it is stated to have been owing to his mea- 
 sures, that a confederate council was held at Athens composed 
 of seventy-five independent states"^'. His fame was enhanced 
 by the eloquence of Isocrates, who (as Polybius and Pansetius 
 followed the fortunes of Scipio) accompanied him as a friend in 
 his campaigns, and wrote his official letters and dispatches to 
 the Athenians: the statue of this orator had also been offered 
 up in the temple at Eleusis by Timotheus^^^ The newly dis- 
 
 ^^' Diod. XV. 38, Nepos Timoth. 2, j are Xenoph. Hell. v. 4, G4 sqq. Diod. 
 Isocrat. de Antidosi p. 69, ed. Orell. ; xv. 36, 47 sqq. and Nepos. 
 Concerning the treaty in Olymp. 102, 4^ j *^^ Nepos and Diodonis. 
 see Xenoph. Hellen. vii. 1, Diod. xv. \ "^^^ /Eschin. de Fals. Leg. p.' 247- 
 
 67. 
 
 ■*8* Diod. XV. 81, and tlie commen- 
 tators. 
 
 "^^'^ The most important passages 
 
 Diodorus (xv. 30,) incorrectly states 
 that the number was 70. 
 
 ^88 Vit. Dec. Orat. pp. 237,241. 
 
 2 E
 
 418 
 
 THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS [bK. IIJ 
 
 covered part of the oration concerning the exchange^'^^ raises a 
 monument to the memory of this unfortmiate warrior, by which 
 the reader is in some measure recompensed for the great tedious- 
 ness of the remainder. After his time no general ever made 
 such important conquests as Timotheus, who subdued no fewer 
 than twenty-four cities of sufficient importance to dehver the 
 whole neighbouring country into the powder of the Athenians, 
 among which Corcyra, Samos, Sestos, Crithote, Potidaea, and 
 Torone are particularly mentioned by Isocrates: Corcyra at 
 that time had still a naval force of 80 triremes. He also 
 recalled the attention of the Athenians to the Chersonese, 
 which they had latterly neglected. Yet amidst all these con- 
 quests he was lenient towards the allies, and even to enemies 
 and prisoners; the discipline which he maintained among his 
 troops was exemplary; and while he bore the chief command, 
 nothing was knowm of banishments, of massacres or expulsions 
 of the inhabitants, of the dissolution of governments, or the 
 devastation of cities. 
 
 The new alliance of the Athenians, as it existed after Olymp. 
 100, 4 (b.c. 377)5 was at first founded upon milder principles 
 than the ancient confederacy. Those states which were by 
 treaty independent, formed a confederate council at Athens 
 {avviBptovY^^, in which they had a seat and vote without any 
 distinction, under the presidency and guidance of Athens: 
 Thebes likewise joined this congress. The name of Synedrion, 
 which obtained general notoriety through the influence of the 
 Macedonian government, was unquestionably not used in this 
 instance for the first time. Herodotus"^ ^ indeed employs it in 
 speaking of a confederate council of ^var; and although it may 
 have been in accordance with the custom of later times that 
 Diodorus"*^^ applies this term to the ancient council of the Athe- 
 nian alliance, it is nevertheless certain that the council of 
 Amphictyons and other confederate assemblies*^'', and even the 
 
 ^«9 P. C,6 sqq. cd. OrcU. 
 
 ■=»" Diod. XV. 28. 
 
 "»' viii. 75, 79. 
 
 ^»* xi. 70. 
 
 *»3 Cf. Domostli. de Corona, p. 232, 
 
 19, -^schin. c. Ctesipli. pp. 445, 44G, 
 p. 513, p. 645, and elsewhere fre- 
 quently. For the expression used I 
 may also quote Lex. Seg. p. 302, Siire-
 
 CH. XVII.] AFTER THE ANARCHY. 419 
 
 Areopagus and the courts, were generally so called in the age 
 of Demosthenes. The Athenians immediately abolished their 
 cleruchise upon the establishment of this council, and passed a 
 law prohibiting all Athenians from the cultivation of any land 
 out of Attica''^'', wishing by this measure to show the allies how 
 greatly they repented of tlieir former injustice. The tributes 
 were also again introduced; but the Athenians, in order to soften 
 this odious name, now called them contributions {awrd^eLsY^^ ; 
 the merit of which invention belonged to Callistratus : hence 
 it is manifest that this was the period at which it first came 
 into use; for in Olymp. 100, 4 (b.c. 377)? this orator filled the 
 situation of general together with Timotheus and Chabrias''^^ 
 and subsequently also (Olymp. 100, 4, B.C. 373), together with 
 Chabrias and Iphicrates, not so much on account of his military 
 qualities as of his political dexterity"' '^j which at this time was 
 an essential requisite in a general. 
 
 The leniency of the Athenians was not, however, of long 
 duration, and the allies, with the exception of Thebes, whose 
 connexion with Athens was altogether voluntary, relapsed into 
 their former oppressed condition; the Athenians distributed 
 garrisons among the several cities, and the tribute was again 
 made compulsory. For this reason it was again known by its 
 ancient name {(f>6po<s), which occurs in some writers''^^: Iso- 
 crates expressly remarks"^^ that the Athenians forced the allied 
 cities to pay contributions (o-fi/Taf et?), which vrere as in ancient 
 times collected by fleets sent out for that purpose^^", and also 
 to send representatives to the council at Athens; the limits of 
 
 'Adrjvaiaiv ^ovkevofievoL nepl Tcbv npay- I Timotheus. Isocrates Paxiath.44,joins 
 fxarcov. [See Mliller's Dorians, vol. i. j avvrd^eLs kol (popovs. The awrd^eis 
 app. 4. Engl. Transl.— Traxsl.] ' frequently occur in other places in 
 
 ■^"■* Diod. XV. 29. i Isocrates, Areopag. i. de Antid. p. 70, 
 
 "" Plutarch. Solon. 15, Harpocrat. | ed. Orell. where he mentions the avv- 
 Phot. in V. avin-a^L9, cf. Lex. Seg. p. , rd^eis ras dno QpaKTjs in the time of 
 300, also Spanheim ad Julian, i. p. 166. | Timotheus, and elsewhere. Concern- 
 Diod. XV. 29. ' ing the ganisons see Isocrat. Svy^t/xa^. 6. 
 
 496 
 
 457 Xenoph. Hellen. vi. 3, ad fin. | ^^^ Sv/Lt/zax. 11, which oration faUs 
 who calls him ev ^idXa e7nTT}beiov ovra, ■ about the end of the Social war. 
 as it should evidently be written. ; '^"^ Plutarch. Phot. 7- This accoimt 
 
 ^^^ iElian. V. II. ii. 10, uses this of the vrja-icoTiKal o-vvrd^eis belongs to 
 word in a story relating to the time of the times of Chabrias. 
 
 2 E 2
 
 420 THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS [bK. III. 
 
 their independence must therefore have been very confined. 
 The Athenians also appear to have fixed the tributes arbitra- 
 rily, even in the later times, when their power had undergone a 
 great diminution : to which point a very obscure passage in the 
 oration against Theocrines refers. It is probable that some of 
 the aUies remonstrated on the severity of their burdens, and that 
 this was the object of the decree, which Automedon proposed in 
 favour of the inhabitants of Tenedos, and which Theocrines 
 attempted to overthrow in its first stage, on the plea that it was 
 contrary to law. A similar decree was carried by Thucydides 
 in favour of the .Enians in Thrace, who continued to pay a 
 tril)ute from the period of the Peloponnesian war down to the 
 times of Philip. This law of Charinus and Theocrines w^hich 
 referred to the contribution [avvra^Ls) being also attached as 
 illegal, and having been in consequence rejected by the people, 
 the ^nians were forced to pay the same amount of tribute 
 as they had formerly given to Chares, on which account they 
 revolted and took in a garrison of barbarians^*'^ 
 
 It is to these later tributes that the oration of Jason in 
 Xenophon refers^°% w*here no notice is taken of the new appel- 
 lation, although subsequently allusion is made to the ancient 
 name; and thus it is better to refer to the time of the new 
 imposts (betw^een the 100th and 105th Olympiads, B.C. 380-57) 
 the statement of Xenophon in his Essay upon the State of 
 Athens^*'^ that the tributes were generally fixed every four 
 years, although the new expression is not made use of; for we 
 have no evidence that before the Anarchy the tributes w^ere 
 fixed every four years. It is indeed upon the whole more pro- 
 bable that the assessment of Aristides remained in force until 
 
 "*' Orat. c. Tlieocrin. pp. 1333, 1334, (?. e. compared with the Athenians) 
 
 ■wliere the words o QovKvhihrjs eine fir] els VTjavdpia drro^XeTrovTas, dXX' 
 
 should be restored, and Alvlovs should TjTreipcoTiKa edvrj Kapnovixevovs. Tlavra 
 
 be written with Taylor for ivlovs,' the yap hr^Ttov to. kvkXo) (f}6pov (jiepei, orav 
 
 reading of the manuscripts. Concern- rayevTjrai to. Kara QeTraXiav. 
 
 ing the tributaiy condition of the ^"^ 3^ 5^ ^^r^u at rd^eis tov <f)6pov 
 
 ^nians as well as the Tenedians in tovto de yiyuerai cos to. noXKa di erovs 
 
 earlier times, see Thucyd. vii. 57. TrepTrrov. The expression (popos also 
 
 ^'* Hellen. vi. 1, 4, Kal xpw<^(^^ 7^ occurs there in diap. 2, 1. See above 
 
 drjTrnv eiKus r)pus (i(f)dovcoTepnis XPW^"!^ note 82.
 
 ClI. XVII.] AFTER THE ANARCHY. 421 
 
 the 89th Olympiad (b.c. 421), and that shortly afterwards the 
 tributes were abolished and a custom duty levied in their 
 place : so that there would be difficulties in referring this pas- 
 sage to the ancient tribute. It is also highly probable that the 
 compulsory jurisdiction, which is mentioned in that Essay, was 
 again forced upon the allies by the growing strength and inso- 
 lence of the Athenians, this being the only means by which 
 Athens could ensure the adherence of the allied states. Nor 
 can our supposition be denied upon the authority of Isocrates, 
 who in the Panathenaic oration mentions the compulsory 
 attendance of the allies at Athens for the decision of their law 
 suits among the ancient misdeeds of the Athenians^"*: for 
 this speech was composed at a very late period (about Olymp. 
 109, 2, B.C. 343), at which time the prohibition of justice 
 to the allied states, even if we suppose that it was again intro- 
 duced after the battle of Cnidos and the 100th Olympiad, 
 might have been spoken of as an ancient occurrence, if, as 
 ajipears probable, it was abolished in the peace of Olymp. 
 106, 1 (B.C. 356). 
 
 Whatever may have been the arrangement with regard to 
 this particular point, it is evident from the consequences which 
 ensued, that the allies were deprived of their independence, and 
 that this was replaced by an intolerable yoke, which the subject 
 states soon endeavoured to shake off. In Olymp. 104, 1 (b.c 
 364), Chios, Byzantium, and Rhodes, had entered into cor- 
 respondence with Epaminondas^''': at length, in Olymp. 105, 3 
 (b.c. 358), they formally revolted, together with the Coans, who 
 had rebelled in Olymp. 103, 3 (b.c. 366)'"'; Byzantium even 
 attempted to obtain a separate dominion, and after the Social 
 war was still in possession of Chalcedon and Selymbria, 
 both which towns were once under the dominion of Athens : 
 
 •■*°* Chap. 23, 24, rdi re diKas kul ras 
 KpiaeLS Tcis ev6dde yiyvofxevas Tols crvfx- 
 fj-axois, and afterwards, olov Kal vvv, 
 rjv ixvTjcrdcJcn Ta>v dyoivcov rav Tols crvfx- 
 fxdxois evddde yevofievcov, Tis eariv ovtcos I seling. 
 d(fiVT]s, oaris ovx fvprjtrec irpos tovt '"" Diod. xv. 76. 
 
 dvT€i7T€'iu, on nXeiovs XuKedaifJiouioi twv \ 
 
 ^YiKkr^vciiv aKpiTovs dTTCKTovucri twv Trap 
 rjfMv, e^ ov TTjv noXiv oiKovpeVy els 
 dycova Kai Kpicnv KaTaaTdvTwv. 
 
 ^"^ Diod. XV. 79, and there Wes-
 
 422 THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS [bK. III. 
 
 and according to the conditions of the treaty, the one was to 
 belong to the king, and the other to be independent^*'^ This 
 war, which lasted until Olymp. 106, 1 (b.c. 356), ruined the 
 finances of Athens by its enormous expenses, the loss of the 
 tributes, and the desolation of the Athenian islands, and ended 
 with the independence of the revolted states. During this war 
 several Tliracian allies were also lost, of which some, as Amphi- 
 polis, became independent, and some were taken away from 
 Athens by Philip, such as the cities of Pydna and Potidaea, 
 which were given to the Olynthians. Thus the revenues 
 received from the tributes were necessarily much diminished 
 at the breaking out of the Sacred war (Olymp. 106, 2, b.c. 
 355). 
 
 The cities of Euboea were afterwards detached from the 
 Athenian alliance by the Macedonians; the remaining posses- 
 sions in Thrace and in the Chersonese were taken, the state 
 gradually lost the seventy-five cities which had been combined 
 by Timotheus into the confederate council, together with 150 
 ships, and large sums of money^°^ Athens, however, up to the 
 period of her complete downfall was never entirely destitute of 
 allies : although in latter times she was unable either to j^rotect 
 them or to assert her own rights. Even pirates disputed for 
 possession with the Athenians; and the contest was no longer 
 confined to the independent states, but extended to the islands 
 which had been the peculiar property of Athens, since Philip 
 attacked even Lemnos, Imbros, and Scyros^°^ 
 
 Concerning the amount of the tributes in the times which 
 succeeded the breaking out of the Social war, our knowledge is 
 most imperfect. Without dwelling upon the erroneous state- 
 ment, that in the time of Lycurgus they still amounted to 1 200 
 talents, we may notice their inconsiderable amount at the time 
 when after the Social war, and at the end of the 106th Olympiad 
 (b.c. 353), Demosthenes came forward against Philip. At that 
 time none but the weakest islands were attached to Athens, not 
 Chios, or Rhodes, or Corcyra; the whole contribution {avvra^csi) 
 
 •'•07 Demosth. de Libert. Ilhod. p. l ^^^ ^Eschin. do F.als. Leg. p. 247. 
 198. I *^^ /Eschin. de Fals. Leg. p. 251.
 
 CH. XVII.] 
 
 AFTER THE ANARCHY. 
 
 423 
 
 amounted only to 45 talents, and even this small sum was 
 raised in advance^ '°. 
 
 Demosthenes succeeded in acquiring more powerful allies, 
 the Euboeans, Achaeans, Corinthians, Thebans, Megarians, 
 Leucadians, and Corcyrseans; the contributions of the states 
 must however have been less compulsory than they had been in 
 more ancient times, ^schines speaks of the unfortunate 
 islanders, who at the time of Chares were forced to pay a yearly 
 contribution [auvra^is:) of 60 talents*' ^ It is possible that 
 these payments subsequently rose to 130 or even to 400 
 talents; although this fact does not admit of proof, and can 
 only be assumed for the purpose of explaining a passage in 
 the fourth Philippic, of w^hich I will presently speak^^*. 
 From this also we might explain the credit w^hich Demosthenes 
 obtained, for having procured from the allies contributions 
 (crvvTa^ets ')(^pr]^dT(av) of more than 500 talents. 
 
 Of the respective allotments we know nothing, except that, 
 in the time of Philip, Eretria and Oreus in Euboea paid 5 
 talents, each under the name of contribution, which, according 
 to the account of ^schines, were lost through the fault of 
 Demosthenes. This orator^' ^ states, upon the authority of a 
 report of Callias the Chalcidean, which he himself disbelieved, 
 that an Euboean council {avviSpcov) existed at Chalcis, which 
 produced a contribution {avvra^is) of 40 talents; and also 
 another of all the Acheeans and Megarians, which supplied a 
 contribution of 60 talents; that the same Callias had also 
 stated that many other states were preparing for war, and that 
 they all wished to form themselves at Athens into a common 
 confederate council, and take the field against Macedon, under 
 the command of Athens. He proceeds to mention, that in 
 consequence of these proceedings the Athenians, at the insti- 
 
 = ^» Demosth. de Corona, p. 305. 
 
 ^" ^scliin. de Fals. Leg. p. 250. 
 
 ^'■^ See chap. 19. Concerning De- 
 mosthenes see the decree after the 
 Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 276. 
 
 513 C. Ctesiph. pp. 482—497. At 
 the conchision of this subject I may 
 remark that the passage of Hyperides 
 
 in the Delian oration in Hai-pocration 
 in V. avvra^is: 2vvTa^iv iv r&i napovri 
 ov8ev\ didovres, r]fxe7s 8e nore rj^tdxrafiev 
 Xa/Seii/, is not to be imderstood of all 
 the allies, but probably only refers to 
 the Delians, who were independent at 
 the time when that oration was com- 
 posed.
 
 424 THE TRIBUTES AND ALLIES OF ATHENS. [bK. III. 
 
 gation of Demosthenes, had remitted tlie contril^ution to the 
 Eretrians and the Oreitans, in order that both states might 
 contril^ute to the Euboean council at Chalcis, while Chalcis 
 itself should cease to belong to the allied council of Athens, 
 and pay to it any contribution ; that by this means Callias had 
 wished to make Euboea independent, and had therefore urged 
 the formation of the council at Chalcis; but that Demosthenes, 
 having been bribed to support this measure, received 3 talents, 
 1 from Chalcis through the hands of CalUas, and 1 from each 
 of the other two cities. As the amount of the sums contributed 
 was so considerable, it is quite possible that the receipts may at 
 that time have equalled several hundred talents. 
 
 Chapter XVIIL 
 The Athenian Cleruchia, or Colonies. 
 
 I have as yet intentionally omitted a subject which is essential 
 to a full understanding of the Athenian alliance, and which by 
 reason of its influence upon the national wealth should on no 
 account be wanting in a history of the public economy of 
 Athens; I mean the Athenian cleruchiae, in the consideration 
 of which, I shall only touch upon some of those points which 
 have escaped the notice of others, in the hope that some future 
 writer will carry on the investigation. 
 
 It was always considered as a right of conquest to divide the 
 lands of the conquered people into lots or freehold estates 
 {KXrjpot); in this manner the Grecians peopled many cities and 
 countries which had previously been in the possession of bar- 
 barians; thus, for example, Athens colonized Amphipolis, which 
 she took from the Edoni. This sort of cleruchia had never 
 any appearance of singularity or harshness, because none but 
 barbarians, who seemed born for slavery, were injured by it. 
 
 This system of colonizing was, however, more rare between 
 Greeks and Greeks. The principal example is afforded by the 
 Dorians, who, on the return of the Heraclidee into the Pelopon- 
 nese, expelled the majority of the ancient inhabitants, and took 
 possession of their lands, to which they had no other right than
 
 CH. XVIII.] THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHI.*:. 425 
 
 that which was obtained by conquest. In like manner also the 
 Thessalian knights appropriated to themselves the lands of the 
 ancient inhabitants^ the Penestee; who became their bondsmen 
 and the cultivators of their lands at a rent: and again in 
 Crete and Lacedaemon the right of conquest had introduced 
 a similar relation between the citizens and the Clarot^^ Mes- 
 senians^ and Helots, and in Rome between the patrons and the 
 clients. 
 
 In these cases the proprietors of the new estates were no other 
 than cleruchi, and their ownership was a cleruchia^'*; and it 
 would be unjust to the Athenians, if we reproached them with 
 the invention of this practice, which is to be considered rather 
 as a remnant of the barbarous treatment of conquered enemies 
 which prevailed in early times; although it appears more unna- 
 tural at a period when mankind had ceased to wander about in 
 large bodies, and had adopted some settled habitation, and also 
 when the severity was exercised towards nations of the same 
 race. In other respects this practice differed so little from the 
 establishment of other colonies, that Polybius, Dionysius, and 
 others, call the Roman colonists cleruchi. 
 
 All motives of revenge and hatred against enemies being 
 left out of the question, it may be said that excess of population 
 and excessive poverty of the citizens were the immediate in- 
 ducements which caused Athens to retain this ancient practice 
 of conquerors. In later times, however, when the system of 
 the Athenian alliance had taken a settled form, reasons of state 
 policy were added to these inducements. The distribution of 
 the land was employed as a caution against, and penalty for, 
 revolt; and the Athenians perceived that there was no cheaper 
 or better method of maintaining the supremacy, as Machiavelli 
 has most justly remarked, than the establishment of colonies, 
 which would be compelled to exert themselves for their own 
 interest to retain possession of the conquered countries : but in 
 this calculation they were so blinded by passion and avarice, as 
 to fail to perceive that their measures excited a lasting hatred 
 
 Concerning the term see Harpocrat. Phot. Suid. Lex. Seg. p. 267, &c.
 
 426 
 
 THE ATiiEXlAX CLERUCIII.E. 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 against the oppressors ; from the consequences of which over- 
 sight Athens suffered severely. 
 
 Isocrates'^^ truly says that the Athenians established cle- 
 ruchi in the desolated towns for the purpose of custody; but he 
 forgets to mention that the Athenians had themselves been the 
 authors of their desolation; and no one will suppose that they 
 were actuated in those proceedings by disinterested motives. 
 Or are we to call it disinterestedness when one state endows its 
 poor citizens with lands at the cost of another? Now it was of 
 this class of persons that the settlers were chiefly composed^ 
 and the state provided them with arms^ and defrayed the 
 expenses of their journey^^^ It is nevertheless true, that the 
 lands were distributed by lot among a fixed number of citizens^^^: 
 the principle of division doubtless was, that all who mshed to 
 partake in the benefit applied voluntarily, and it was then 
 determined by lot who should and who should not receive a 
 share. If any wealthy person wished to go out as a fellow-^ 
 speculator, full liberty must necessarily have been granted him. 
 The profitableness of the concern forbids us to imagine that all 
 the citizens cast lots, and that those upon whom the chance fell 
 were compelled to become cleruchi. 
 
 With regard to the first introduction of the Athenian 
 cleruchies, it may be observed, that the earliest instance occurs 
 before the Persian wars, when the lands of the knights 
 (tTTTToySorat) of Chalcis in Euboea were given to 4000 Athenian 
 citizens, other estates being at the same time retained for the 
 gods and the state^'®. In the Peloponnesian war, however, 
 Chalcis had ceased to be a state of cleruchi, for it is mentioned 
 among the tributary allies, separately from the Athenian colo- 
 nies^' ^. In what relation the ancient cleruchi stood to the 
 natives, and whether the latter (who were partly common 
 people, and partly descendants of the knights formerly liberated 
 by the Athenians for a ransom) shared the governing power 
 
 ^'^ PanegjT. p. 85, ed. Hall. 
 
 *'^ Liban. Argum. ad Demosth. de 
 Cliersoneso. 
 
 ^^' Thucyd. iii. 50, Plutarch. Pericl. 
 34. 
 
 ^^' Herod, v. 77, vi. 100, ^lian. Var, 
 Hist, vi, 1, where the text is corrupt; 
 for in Herodotus it is evident that no 
 alteration can be made. 
 
 *'» Thuoyd. vii. 57, cf. vi. 7C.
 
 CH. XVIII.] THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHI.E. 427 
 
 with the Athenian cleruchi, or whether the cleruchi, who 
 returned to the main-land upon the Persian attack of Eretria, 
 were not restored to their cleruchiae, are questions which I shall 
 not attempt to determine. The next case of this kind was the 
 enslaving of the Dolopes and Pelasgians of Scyros, in the time 
 of Cimon, when the island was settled with cleruchi*-": in like 
 manner the islands of Lemnos and Imbros belonged to the 
 Athenians. 
 
 The distribution of lands was of most frequent occurrence 
 after the administration of Pericles. Pericles himself and his 
 successors^ Alcibiades^ Cieon^ and other statesmen, employed it 
 as a means of gaining the favour of the needy citizens^^^; and 
 the fondness of the common Athenians for this measure may 
 be seen from the example of Strepsiades in the Clouds of x\ris- 
 tophanes, vrho, on the mention of the word geometry, is 
 instantly reminded of measuring out the lands of cleruchi*^^ 
 Thus in Olymp. 83, 4 (b.c. 445), Histieea in Euboea was given 
 to cleruchi^", and at a later period Potidaea, the inhabitants of 
 which were expelled: the same course was also followed with 
 ^gina, at the breaking out of the Peloponnesian war, and the 
 Dorian people were ejected^-"*. Delos was indeed again depo- 
 pulated, but not entirely surrendered to the Athenians until a 
 subsequent period, when it had become nearly desolate. Lesbos 
 however they divided^ with the exception of Methymna, after 
 the revolt of the Mytileneans: at Scione the adult men were 
 put to death, the women and children made slaves, and the 
 PlatcEans wxre established in possession of the city, as being 
 Athenian citizens destitute of land*^': the Melians were also 
 reduced to slavery, and their property granted to cleruchi^*^ 
 Many other cleruchi were also sent out upon the instigation of 
 
 ^^'^ Thuc. i. 98, Diod. xi. 60, Nepos 
 Cimon. 2. 
 
 ^^' Plutarch, ubi sup. cf. Aristoph. 
 Vesp. 714. 
 
 *** Nub. 203, and the Scholia&t, with 
 
 a calculation founded upon the amount 
 of diobelia the author coujectui'es that 
 the colonists of iEgiua were about 
 1400 or 1500. Corp. Inscript. No. 148, 
 vol. i. p. 227.— Thaksl.] 
 
 the notes of the commentators. i ^" Thuc. v. 32, Diod. xii. 76. Cf. 
 
 5^ Thuc. i. 114, cf. vii. 57, Died. xii. ! Isocrat. Panegp*. pp. 85, 80. 
 22. ' I ^^^ Thuc. V. ad fin. 
 
 "^ Thuc. ii. 27, Diod. xii. 44. [From [
 
 428 
 
 THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHI.E. 
 
 [^BK. 
 
 [I. 
 
 Pericles. This statesman sent 1000 men to the Chersonese, 
 500 to Naxos, 250 to Andros, 1000 to Thrace, without reckoning 
 those that went to ^Egina, Thurii, and other places" ^ In 
 Euboea, from which, on account of its proximity to Attica, the 
 greatest advantages were reasonably expected, they manifestly 
 seized upon much land^"; hence ^schines^" asserts, that at 
 the time which immediately succeeded the peace of Nicias, 
 Athens was in possession of the Chersonese, Naxos, and 
 Euboea; of the latter island more than two-thirds, as An decides 
 attests in his oration concerning peace^^". 
 
 There can be no doubt that all the cleruchise were lost by 
 the battle of ^gospotamos"'; but as soon as they had suffi- 
 cient power, the Athenians established new colonies. In the 
 100th Olympiad the odium which they incurred on account of 
 these settlements was so great, that they recalled them^^^: but 
 the law which prohibited any Athenian from owning landed 
 property out of Attica did not long remain in force. Demos- 
 thenes speaks of cleruchian property in the 106th Olympiad 
 (B.C. 354)'". In Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353), they again sent 
 cleruchi to the Chersonese, who were admitted by some cities; 
 the Cardiani however excluded them'^\ Samos was in Olymp. 
 107, 1 (B.C. 352), settled with 2000 cleruchi"% not without the 
 
 5^7 Plutarcli Pericl. 11. 
 
 528 Cf. Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 314, 
 Demosth. Lept. 95, and there Wolf, 
 Moms ad Isocrat. Pan eg. 31. 
 
 5^9 De Fals. Leg. p. 337- 
 
 530 P. 93. Here actual possession, 
 and not subjection only, is meant, as is 
 evident from the circumstances of the 
 case. Comp. also Aristoph. Vesp. 714. 
 
 521 Cf. Xenoph, Mem. Socrat. ii. 
 7,8. 
 
 53^ Diod. XV. 23, 29. 
 
 533 In his speech concerning the 
 Symmorise. 
 
 53* Demosth. de Cherson. p. 91, 15, 
 Philipp. Epist. ap. Demosth. p. 163, 5, 
 Diod. xvi. 34, Liban. Argum. in Orat. 
 de Cherson. 
 
 535 Strab. xiv. p. 439, Ilcraclid. 
 
 Fragm. de Repub. 10, where Kdhler's 
 long note contains nothing, Diog. 
 Laert. x. 1, Diod. xviii. 8, ^Eschin, c. 
 Timarch. p. 78, Zenob. ii. 28. For the 
 date, I follow the statement of Pliilo- 
 chorus (ap. Dionys. in Vit. Dinarch. 
 p. 118, ed. Sylb.) in preference to the 
 Scholiast of ^schines (p. 731, vol. iii. 
 ed. Reisk.) who states that it was in 
 the archonship of Nicophemus (Olymp. 
 104, 4, B.C. 361). Diodorus xviii. 18, 
 does not agree with either, as he 
 reckons forty-three years from the ex- 
 pulsion of the Samians until their re- 
 storation by Perdicca.s in Olymp. 114, 
 2 (B.C. 323). There is however un- 
 questionably some error in this pas- 
 sage, which has been well examined by 
 Wesselinjr.
 
 CH. XVIIl.] THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHI^. 429 
 
 disapprobation of those ^yho were under the influence of better 
 principles"^ 
 
 But what was the relation which the states of the cleruchi 
 bore to Athens? Did the cleruchi remain Athenian citizens, 
 and if they did, were they at the same time citizens of a com- 
 munity composed of the cleruchi ? If this was the case, are 
 they to be considered as Athenian allies? and if so, in what 
 manner, whether dependent or independent? 
 
 Of these questions some can only be answered by conjec- 
 ture. That the cleruchi remained Athenian citizens cannot be 
 a matter of any doubt, whether we look to the views of Athens 
 in the establishment of cleruchi, or to the reasons by which 
 individuals could be actuated in accepting cleruchiee. The only 
 objects which Athens could have had, were either to enrich the 
 poor citizens, or to maintain important stations or countries for 
 its own advantage. But if the cleruchi had ceased to be citi- 
 zens of Athens, the benefit received by the parent state would 
 have been lost. These establishments of cleruchi would in that 
 case have become mere colonies, unconnected with Athens by 
 any close relation, analogously to the lonians in Asia Minor 
 and the islands, who, although they had proceeded from Attica, 
 soon broke off all connexion with the mother-country. x\nd 
 who would have sacrificed his rights of citizenship, which were 
 so highly prized by the Greeks, for the possession of an estate, 
 if he was moreover exposed to the risk, in case the former pro- 
 prietors were reinstated either by war or treaty, of being left 
 not only without property, but even without a country? ^s- 
 chines speaks of a person who had gone with the cleruchi to 
 Samos, as if he were merely an absent Athenian; and Demos- 
 thenes includes the property of the cleruchi among that of 
 Attica. Aristophanes the poet possessed an estate in ^Egina, 
 during the time that he was an Athenian citizen"^: Aristarchus, 
 a person mentioned in Xenophon, who was a citizen and a pro- 
 
 ^« Aristot. Rhet. ii. 6. 
 
 537 Aristopli. Acliarn. 652, accord- 
 
 The Callistratus mentioned by the 
 other Scholiast, Avho also possessed a 
 
 ing to the correct interpretation of one ' portion of land in /Egina, cannot be 
 Scholiast. Cf. Aristoph. Vit. p. 14. meant in this passage.
 
 430 THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHl^. [bK. III. 
 
 i:)rietor of houses at Athens, and whose estates had fallen into 
 the hands of the enemy, was both a citizen and a cleruchus ; 
 as also Eutherus, who had lost his foreign estates, and com- 
 plains that his father had not even left him anything in 
 Attica"'. Demosthenes also appears to consider the inhabi- 
 tants of Lemnos and Imbros as Athenian citizens"'; and 
 although Ariston the father of Plato went as a cleruchus to 
 ^gina, and Plato himself was born there (Olymp. 87, 3, B.C. 
 430); although Neocles the father of Epicurus settled in Samos 
 wdth the cleruchi^^% and his son was educated in that island; it 
 is nevertheless certain that Plato and Epicurus were, as well as 
 their fathers, Athenian citizens, the former belonging to the 
 borough Collyttus, the latter to the borough Gargettus, and 
 that after their return, they were considered as natives equally 
 with citizens born in Attica. 
 
 But, notwithstanding this privilege of the cleruchi, in the 
 states w^hich were exclusively possessed by them they composed 
 a separate community: this fact might indeed have been in- 
 ferred from the general policy of the Greeks, according to which 
 the inhabitants of each place formed themselves into a separate 
 community, administering its own government. Again, as the 
 cleruchiee must be considered as colonies (with this one excep- 
 tion, that they were more closely dependent upon the mother 
 country than the early settlements), it was indispensable that 
 they should compose a separate state: hence they are called by 
 a new appellation, as Amphipolitans, Istieeans, Chalcideans, 
 ^ginetans^*^; although they are sometimes also called Athe- 
 nians; for by the international law of Greece it was permitted 
 that one person should at the same time be a citizen of several 
 states, and even all the citizens of one state frequently received 
 the rights of citizenship in another. 
 
 It sometimes however happened that the cleruchi, as was the 
 
 *38 See tlie passages of /EscliiuGs, 
 Demosthenes, and Xenoplion, in notes 
 535, 533,531. 
 
 539 Demostli. Philip, i.p. 49, 2C. 
 
 ^^^ Phavorin. ap. Diogen. Laert. iii. 
 2, Ileraclid. ap. eund. x. 1. 
 
 viii. 1, 4G, Pansan. v. 23. The Athe- 
 nians in Delos in later times indeed 
 called themselves " the People of the 
 Athenians in Delos ;" but from a pe- 
 riod so recent no conclusion can he 
 drawn which will apply to earlier 
 
 *^' Thucyd. iv. 104, vii. 47, Tlerod. times. Sec above note 430.
 
 CTI. XVIII.] THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHI/E. 431 
 
 case in Mytilene, did not personally occupy the property, hut 
 held it as landlords. In this case then are we to imagine that 
 they composed a separate colony? After the revolt and recon- 
 quest of Mytilene, more than 1000 of the chief persons were 
 executed, the small cities of the Mytileneans were separated 
 from Lesbos, and reduced to the condition of subject alhes of 
 Athens. No tribute was imposed upon the Mytileneans them- 
 selves, but the country was divided into 3000 lots, of which 300 
 were reserved as tithes for the gods, and the others were given 
 to the cleruchi who were sent to Lesbos : the cultivation of the 
 land was then permitted to the Lesbians themselves, in con- 
 sideration of a rent of 2 minas for each lot^'*^. Now althouo^h 
 Thucydides undoubtedly states that the cleruchi were sent 
 thither, it is impossible to believe that 2700 Athenians remained 
 in this island, as in that case the whole countiy would hardly 
 have been granted in lease to the Lesbians. There can be no 
 doubt that many Athenians returned home; but a part of the 
 settlers must have stayed behind as a garrison, and probably 
 these, together with the former inhabitants, composed the com- 
 monwealth. 
 
 Lastly, from the nature of the cleruchian communities it may 
 be inferred, that although their citizens were also citizens of 
 Athens, they nevertheless remained in the most entire depend- 
 ence upon the mother country. In the first place the religious 
 institutions of the cleruchi were, as well as their priests, con- 
 nected with those of Athens, the religion of all colonies having 
 been originally derived from the mother state. Again, there 
 was no obstacle which could prevent the government of Athens 
 from retaining large estates in those countries as pubUc pro- 
 perty, either as consecrated to the gods, as in Chalcis and Les- 
 bos, or as belonging directly to the Athenian state, as was the 
 case in Chalcis, and probably with the Thracian mines**^ A 
 community of such colonists was evidently debarred from the 
 privilege of maintaining a separate military force, in which 
 
 5^^ Thucyd. iii. 50. Antiplion de j xiii. p. 412, and there Ciisaubon, Time. 
 Herod, ciede p. 744. Concerning the iv. 52, Herod, v. 94 sqq. 
 towns upon the main-land see Strab. -^^^ See book iii. ch. 2 and 3.
 
 432 THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHIiE. [bK. III. 
 
 respect it must have been wholly dependent upon Athens. 
 Hence we find that the Chalcidean cleruchi had no vessels of 
 their own at Artemisium and Salamis, but they manned 20 
 Athenian triremes*", for which the 4000 cleruchi were exactly 
 sufficient; and they received from Athens instructions for mili- 
 tary undertakings^*^ Their generals were doubtless nominated 
 by Athens; and although perhaps they had the privilege of 
 appointing to many public offices, they were yet subject to the 
 control of inspectors sent from Athens, and indeed in many 
 other colonies the mother state had the right of nominating to 
 certain situations. It must also have been considered by the 
 cleruchi as a right allowed to them and not as an obligation, 
 that they were under the jurisdiction of the Athenian courts; 
 for otherwise the cleruchus would have renounced an essential 
 privilege of the Athenian citizen. 
 
 And what we have already said upon the authority of Anti- 
 phon concerning the limited jurisdiction of the Mytileneans 
 after their revolt, proves that the supreme jurisdiction in the 
 cleruchian communities belonged to Athens, and extended not 
 to the cleruchi only, but also to the ancient inhabitants, who 
 might in the first instance have resorted to courts of the Athe- 
 nian cleruchi. In this manner such states as we have been 
 speaking of fell (although by a path wholly different) into a 
 state of dependence as degraded as that of the subject allies; 
 T\^th this difference only, that they were inhabited by citizens, 
 who would have been entitled to exercise all the risfhts of 
 
 o 
 
 citizenship in Athens itself. 
 
 The only point as to which any doubt can exist is, whether 
 or not they paid a tribute ? Thucydides is silent with regard 
 to them, although in speaking of the other communities he 
 invariably mentions whether they paid a tribute or furnished a 
 military force. The cleruchi, as being Athenian citizens, must 
 necessarily have performed military service for their country: 
 but it is nevertheless possible that particular states were also 
 subject to the payment of a tribute, which perhaps arose 
 from the transfer of the obhgations, together with the 
 
 *" HerocL u])i sup. 545 u^j-oa. vi. 100.
 
 CH. XVIII.] THE ATHENIAN CLERUCHIiE. 433 
 
 transfer of the property which had belonged to the former inha- 
 bitants. Mytilene before its revolt paid no tribute; from which, 
 as is manifest, the cleruchi were equally exempt; for Thucy- 
 dides, having expressly stated that no tribute had been imposed 
 upon the Lesbians, would not have omitted to mention that the 
 Athenians were subject to this burthen, ^gina had been 
 subject to a tribute from the 80th Olympiad; and it seems to 
 me probable that the cleruchi who in the 87th Olympiad were 
 sent in the place of the ancient inhabitants paid the same 
 tribute. At least this enables me to comprehend why in the 
 93rd Olympiad we should meet with an eicostologus in ^gina; 
 the custom duty of a twentieth having succeeded in place of the 
 tribute. I have already remarked, that Chalcis^ which Thucy- 
 dides calls a tributary state, had ceased to be a community of 
 cleruchi in the time of the Peloponnesian war, and therefore 
 that city is unconnected with any discussion upon this point 
 
 Chapter XIX. 
 
 Total Annual Amount of the Public Revenue of Athens. 
 
 From the regular revenues, of which an account has been 
 already given, independently of the liturgies and the extraor- 
 dinary taxes, the sum of the annual income of the Athenian 
 state might be computed, if each single item could be deter- 
 mined for the diiferent periods. But as this is not in every 
 case possible, we must be contented with collecting and passing 
 judgment upon the few statements which the ancients furnish 
 us with. 
 
 I do not stay to consider the absurd assertion made by 
 Petit, Salmasius, Meursius, and others, that the revenue of 
 Athens amounted to 6000 talents a year, but shall immediately 
 turn to the statement of Xenophon, who informs us that on the 
 breaking out of the Peloponnesian war not less than 1000 
 talents were received from domestic and from foreign sources, 
 i. e. from the allies"®. Xenophon evidently considers this sum 
 
 Cyr. Expod. vii. 1, 27. 
 
 2 F
 
 434 TOTAL ANNUAL AMOUNT OF THE [bK. III. 
 
 as extraordinarily large; and if we reckon the tributes at 600 
 talents^ which was their amount at that period, 400 talents 
 remain for the domestic revenue, which corresponds sufficiently 
 well with the resources of the country, and with the necessary 
 regular expenses. The account of the historian is, however, 
 contradicted by the poet Aristophanes, who in the comedy of 
 the Wasps^^^ (Olymp. 89, 2, B.C. 423) estimates the total sum 
 of all the revenues at nearly 2000 talents, exclusively of the 
 liturgies, w^hich were not paid into any public fund. Aristo- 
 phanes indeed reckons many things which Xenophon perhaps 
 might pass over, such as justice fees and fines^ together with 
 the proceeds of confiscated property. This, however, is not 
 sufficient to occasion so large a difference in the statements, 
 nor can it be supposed that Aristophanes would have made any 
 gross exaggeration. Nothing therefore remains but to suppose 
 that the enhancement of the tributes, which is mentioned in 
 the orators as if it had been a consequence of the peace of 
 Nicias, had in fact taken place a short time before, that is to 
 say, about Olymp. 89, 1, or 2 {b.c. 424 — 3). If the increased 
 tribute, as has been already shown, alone amounted to 1200 
 talents, and if we add the items which Xenophon, as has been 
 said, perhaps omitted, the sum obtained would be about 1800 
 talents. 
 
 How great must have been the falling off in this large 
 amount of revenue, when the ascendancy of Athens no longer 
 existed, it is superfluous to point out. After the battle of 
 iEgospotamos all payment of tribute ceased, the traffic was 
 inconsiderable, many houses in Athens were unoccupied, the 
 state was unable to pay off the smallest debts, and was forced 
 to submit to reprisals from the Boeotians for the sake of a few 
 talents. We have not however any determinate statements 
 until the time of Lycurgus, excepting in the fourth Philippic, 
 which, although not the production of Demosthenes, ought not 
 therefore to be neglected; for definite statements must have 
 some foundation even in a spurious oration. ^^ It was once our 
 case,'^ we are there told"^, " and that not long ago, to be pos- 
 
 »^7 Vs. 657 sqq. ^'^ P. 41,9.
 
 CH. XIX.] PUBLIC REVENUE OF ATHENS. 435 
 
 sessed of a public revenue which did not exceed 130 talents;" 
 and the orator presently adds, that good fortune had afterwards 
 increased the public income, and that the receipts amounted to 
 400 instead of 100 talents. It is hardly conceivable that the 
 national income should ever have sunk so low as 130 talents, 
 especially as Lycurgus in the age of Demosthenes is stated to 
 have again succeeded in raising it to 1200 talents. It is how- 
 ever possible that the author of this speech had some passage 
 before him which he misunderstood, and in which the tributes 
 were alluded to. These payments might have amounted to 130 
 and afterwards to 400 talents, and the latter have been in the 
 time of Lycurgus; it would otherwise be incomprehensible 
 to us by what means he could have so much augmented the 
 revenue without the aid of considerable tributes. We must 
 however be satisfied not to pass any decided judgment upon 
 this subject, so many points of it being obscure, as they must 
 always remain. Nor indeed will the statements of Demosthenes 
 and ^Eschines, concerning the tributes in later times, agree 
 with my hypothesis, unless, as is probable, they relate to other 
 years. For what Demosthenes and ^schines say, may be 
 referred to the time of the social war, and then the account of 
 the 130 talents may have reference to the years immediately 
 following, and of the 400 talents to the time beginning in 
 Olymp. 109, 4 (b.c. 341), or Olymp. 110, 1 (b.c. 340), the 
 date assumed by the author of the fourth Philippic for its 
 composition. 
 
 The revenue appears to have sufifered the greatest falling off 
 in the 105th and 106th Olympiads (b.c. 360— 53)*'®, from the con- 
 joint influence of the defection of the allies, and the interruption 
 of trade. It is to this latter evil that Xenophon alludes in his 
 Essay on the Revenues"^ when he complains of the failure of 
 several branches of the public income in time of war. According 
 to Isocrates"' the Athenians were at that time in want of the 
 common necessaries of life, and by extorting money for the 
 
 5" See Demosth c. Leptin. § 21, 95, 
 spoken in OljTnp. 106, 2 (b.c. 355). 
 ^^^ 5, 12, Concerning the time see 
 
 book iv. cb. 21. 
 
 **' ^vfjLfxax- 16, written in Olymp- 
 106, 1 (B.C. 35G). 
 
 2 F 2
 
 436 
 
 TOTAL ANNUAL AMOUNT OF THE 
 
 [bk. 
 
 payment of the mercenaries, utterly ruined tlieir allies: so that, 
 in his opinion, peace was the only means of recovering their 
 prosperity, of putting an end to war taxes, and to the trierarchy, 
 of promoting agriculture, trade, and shipping, of raising the 
 revenues, and increasing the number of merchants, foreigners, 
 and resident aliens, of which the state was absolutely destitute. 
 Demosthenes*** indeed not long afterwards (Olymp. 106, 3 
 (b.c. 354), estimates the wealth of Athens as nearly equal to 
 that of all the other states; but in this comparison he refers 
 only to the national wealth, and not to the public revenue. 
 
 The orator Lycurgus appears to have been the only one 
 amongst the statesmen of ancient times who had a real know- 
 ledge of the management of finance. He was a man of the 
 strictest integrity, and so hardy that he went barefoot, after the 
 manner of Socrates; at the same time judicious, active, econo- 
 mical without parsimony, in all respects of a noble disposition, 
 and so inflexibly just, that he was more willing to give than to 
 take: thus we are told^ that he bestowed a talent upon a syco- 
 phant, to prevent an information being laid against his wife, for 
 the transgression of a law passed by himself; although it is 
 true that he thus deprived the state of a fine*". Although the 
 administration of finance engaged the largest share of his atten- 
 tion, he also attended to other public duties, and in the latter 
 part of his life to foreign aifairs"^ The public revenue was 
 under his management for three periods of five years (Trevrae- 
 T7;ptSe9"'), that is, according to the ancient idiom, twelve 
 years**': the first four years for himself, and the others under 
 the name of another person; but in such a manner, that it w^as 
 known that he was properly the manager of the public revenue. 
 When this administration began, and when it ceased, we are 
 
 *" De Symmor. p. 155, 2. 
 
 553 Taylor ad Lycurg. p. 114, val. iv. 
 Reisk. The defence of Lycurgus iu 
 the assembly may be seen in Plutai'ch's 
 Comparison of Nicias and Crassus, 
 cliap. 1. 
 
 *•'•"' Pseudo-Demosth. Epist. 3. 
 
 "* Decret. in Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 278, 
 Vit. Lycurg. ibid. p. 250, Pliotius 
 
 cclxviii. p. 1483, whose account is 
 chiefly derived from the spurious Plu- 
 tarch, and therefore will not always 
 be quoted separately. 
 
 "^ Diod. xvi. 88. Wesseling (ad 
 Diod. et ad Petit Leg. Att. iii. 2, 33) 
 assumes fifteen years, which appears 
 to me impossible. Comp. above, book 
 ii. ch. fi.
 
 CH. XIX.] PUBLIC REVENUE OF ATHENS. 437 
 
 not indeed informed; nor can the question be settled by the 
 testimony of Diodorus, who mentions it as past, in speaking of 
 the battle of Chaeronea : for it is evident that he only took this 
 opportunity of stating that Lycurgus had distinguished himself 
 by his financial measures. I have however some reasons for 
 supposing that he did not enter upon that office before the 
 109th Olympiad'^^ 
 
 He passed through with honour on the several occasions 
 when he rendered an account of his financial administration" ^ 
 The loss of the accounts which he fixed up previously to his 
 death (a fragment of which is probably still extant*), of his 
 oration concerning the administration (vrepl StoLKrjaecos^^^), and 
 of his defence against Menesgechmus {a7roXoyca-pb09 o)v Treiro- 
 XirevTai, airoXoyla virep tmv evOvvoiv'"^^), in which he justified 
 the accounts that he had set up against the attacks of his^^^ 
 adversary, and in which he entered into minute details, such, 
 for example, as the hide money; the loss of these documents is 
 irreparable for the history of the Athenian finances. When the 
 military preparations were committed to Lycurgus," he built 
 400 vessels, of which some were new and some old vessels 
 repaired; provided a large store of arms, and also 50,000 darts, 
 which were brought to the Acropolis ; procured gold and silver 
 instruments for processions, golden statues of victory, and 
 golden ornaments for 100 canephorae; he also built and planted 
 the gymnasium in the Lyceum, founded the wresthng school in 
 that place, completed many unfinished works, such as the docks, 
 the armoury, the theatre of Bacchus, the panathenaic course, 
 and adorned the city with many other works of art^^^ He 
 also raised the revenue"' (and not the tributes, as Meursius 
 and his followers suppose''') to 1200 talents. The author of 
 
 Corp. Inscript. No. 157, and founded with the Eisangelia against 
 
 notes. 
 
 ^58 Decret. iit sup. p. 279. 
 
 * See note 557. 
 
 *^^ Suid. in w. AvKovpyos, 'ETriKpa-n;?, 
 
 Menesgechmus. 
 
 ^' Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 255. 
 
 56^ Decret. in Vit. Dec. Orat. Phot, 
 ubi sup. Pausan. i. 29. 
 
 oxelov, (xeipiov, Harpocrat. in vv. 'Etti- *^^ Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 254. 
 KpaTrjs, ox^'iou, aeipiva. j ^64 Meurs. Fort. Att. p. 55, Barthel. 
 
 **^*' Concerning which see Meurs. Anarch, vol. iv. p. 33 1 , Manso, Sparta, 
 Bibl. Att. This must not be con- : vol. ii. p. 498.
 
 438 
 
 TOTAL ANNUAL AMOUNT OF THE 
 
 [bk. 
 
 III. 
 
 the Lives of the Ten Orators adds to this statement, singularly- 
 enough, that they formerly amounted to 60 talents; for which 
 number it has been proposed by some to read 600; Meursius 
 however prefers 460, who again refers it to the tributes, and 
 indeed to the assessment of Aristides. It appears to me most 
 probable, that either the ignorant compiler himself, or some 
 commentator who wished to supply the deficiency of his author, 
 had in his mind the 60 talents contributed by the allies, of 
 which ^schines speaks. 
 
 With regard to money stored up for future use, I am upon 
 the whole convinced that Lycurgus did not collect any treasure. 
 Pausanias indeed thought that he had done so, and the decree 
 in favour of Lycurgus states that he brought much money to 
 the Acropolis ; but there can be no doubt that it was soon con- 
 sumed. Distributions were made among the citizens from the 
 surplus money, and nothing remained but what was worked up 
 in ornaments for processions, or in works of art and sacred 
 offerings . Of the measures which he adopted for increasing 
 the public income we are wholly ignorant: it should at the 
 same time be borne in mind, that at this period, when the 
 quantity of money in circulation was considerable, the value of 
 1200 talents was not so great as in the age of Pericles. On 
 account of the extreme honesty of Lycurgus, many private 
 individuals had confided large sums of money to his custody, 
 which in time of need he advanced to the state without requir- 
 ing any interest. In the decree it is stated that this money 
 amounted to 650 talents, but, according to the Lives of the Ten 
 Orators, it was only 250 talents'": the former is the more 
 probable statement. 
 
 The amount of all the monies, for the receipt and disburse- 
 ment of which he accounted, is stated differently. The decree 
 of Stratocles, which was brought forward in the archonship of 
 Anaxicrates (Olymp. 118, 2, b.c. 307), and to which we have 
 
 '^* The origin of Uiis difference pro- 
 bably was, tha t it was written in the 
 decree III H |A| TaXavra, which the 
 author of the Lives of th^ Ten Orators 
 
 read as if it were H H [a7' This is 
 more probable than that the mistake 
 sliould luive been the contrary way.
 
 CH. XIX.] PUBLIC REVENUE OF ATHENS. 439 
 
 SO often referred, mentions 18,900 talents'*^; but in the Lives 
 of the Ten Orators only 18,650 talents are quoted from the 
 same source. Upon which side the error lies may appear 
 doubtful. The passage in the Lives of the Ten Orators is, 
 however, evidently interpolated by some other hand, and is 
 therefore less worthy of credit than the text of the decree, 
 which is the original of that statement ; and it is possible that 
 the number 650 instead of 900 arose from a confusion with the 
 amount of money advanced by private individuals, which occurs 
 immediately afterwards in the decree, and amounts to the very 
 same number. The safest course therefore is to abide by the 
 statement of the decree. 
 
 The whole sum is in another place stated at only 14,000 
 talents^^^: this number appears however to have been arrived at 
 by a mere process of approximation, viz., by multiplying 1200 
 talents, the amount of the annual receipts, by twelve, which 
 gives 14,400 talents, and inaccurately omitting the other 400; 
 whereas the decree of Stratocles must have been founded upon 
 official documents, and doubtless upon the account rendered by 
 Lycurgus himself, and fixed up in public. For it would be 
 absurd to suppose that in so ancient a document, and one which 
 was drawn up for the express use of the state, the number 
 should have been ascertained by an approximate estimate, 
 merely by multiplying 1200 talents by 15, on the assumption 
 that Lycurgus administered the finances for fifteen years. Now 
 it is true that the record of the decree does not agree with the 
 account which states that in the time of Lycurgus the revenue 
 amounted annually to 1 200 talents, if, as has been assumed, he 
 was only at the head of this department for twelve years ; but 
 since he accounted for the money of private individuals, which 
 was afterwards repaid, the sum of the disbursements might 
 have been considerably increased, if the money advanced was 
 included among the payments, and afterwards the money with 
 which these loans were replaced. 
 
 The statement of Pausanias'^® on this subject is also worthy 
 of consideration. This author, in his ambiguous Herodotean 
 
 *^« P. 278. ^*^7 Vit. Dec. Orat. p. 251, Phot, ubi sup. "•* i. 20.
 
 440 
 
 ANNUAL AMOUNT OF PUBLIC REVENUE. [bK. III. 
 
 style, informs us that Lycurgus brought into the pubhc treasure 
 6500 talents more than Pericles; by which he means, the whole 
 amount of what Lycurgus had received and disbursed. Accord- 
 ing to Isocrates, the sum collected by Pericles was 8000 talents: 
 if we suppose that Pausanias folio ^ved some more accurate 
 authority which stated 7900 talents as the amount collected by 
 Pericles, 14,400 talents would be the sum which he meant to 
 say was amassed by Lycurgus, a number which would upon 
 this hypothesis have merely been obtained by an approximate 
 estimate, as has been remarked above. The statement of Pau- 
 sanias cannot be well understood in any other manner. 
 
 Lycurgus was succeeded in the administration by his adver- 
 sary Meneseechmus, and Dionysius is also stated to have been 
 treasurer of the administration (6 kirl ri]^ hioiKrjo-ea)^) at the 
 same period, to both of whom Dinarchus was opposed^*'. 
 Demetrius Phalereus is also praised for having increased the 
 revenue of the state"" after Olymp. 115, 3 (b.c. 318), at a 
 period when Athens had already sunk into comparative insigni- 
 ficance. Nor is it easy to determine what amount of credit 
 should be given to Duris of Samos"^, when he states that the 
 annual revenue of Athens amounted to 1 200 talents in the time 
 of Demetrius. In the later times of the republic the manage- 
 ment must have been more economical, in order to carry the 
 state through its difficulties. We are informed by a decree"* 
 that Demochares, the son of Laches, was the first person who 
 curtailed the expenses of the administration, and made an 
 economical use of the current revenues. The same person also 
 procured gifts for his country from foreigners: 30 talents from 
 Lysimachus, and on another occasion 100 from the same person, 
 50 from Ptolemy, and 20 from Antipater. Thus was this once 
 great nation forced to beg of kings. 
 
 '*^ Concerning these two see Dio- 
 nysius llalicaruassensis in tlic Life of 
 Dinarchus. 
 
 *'<' Diog. Laert. v. 75. 
 
 ^7' Ap. Athen. xii. p. 542, C. 
 
 ^'■' Ap. Vit. Dec. Oral. p. 276.
 
 CH. XX.] HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. 
 
 441 
 
 Chapter XX. 
 
 History of the Public Treasure, 
 
 From the overplus of the national revenue there arose in 
 ancient times the Public Treasure, which at its first formation 
 was exclusively, and afterward in a great measure, applied to 
 the uses of war. 
 
 It was preserved upon the Acropolis, in the posterior cell 
 (oTTtaOoBo/jLos) of a temple of Minerva'"^; but of what temple we 
 are not informed. The scholiast to the Plutus of Aristophanes 
 assures us that it was the temple of Minerva Polias ; that is to 
 say, the threefold temple which belonged to Erectheus, Minerva, 
 and Pandrosus. But this, according to the certain testimony of 
 Herodotus and Pausanias, was burned down by the Persians 
 under Xerxes; in Olymp. 92, 4 (b.c. 409), and even in Olymp. 
 93, 1 (B.C. 408), it had not been rebuilt'^* ; and in the third year 
 of the same Olympiad, in the archonship of CalUas (b.c. 406), 
 it was again burned down'*^^ for the second time. The temple 
 which was afterwards built, as Stuart remarks*'®, had not any 
 opisthodomus, and this is evidently true of the temple which 
 w^as in course of building in Olymp. 92, 4, from its similarity 
 with that of which the remains are still extant, which have been 
 compared by Wilkins with the inscription relating to the unfi- 
 nished temple just mentioned. At no time therefore can the 
 treasure have been deposited in a posterior cell of the temple of 
 
 V '^^ Harpocrat.Suid.Hesych. Etymol. 
 Phot, (twice) in v. oniaOodo^os. Aris- 
 topli. Plut. 1194, Orat. jrepl avvrd^. 
 p. 170, Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 743, 1, 
 and there Ulpian. p. 822, Lucian. Tim. 
 53, also Lex. Seg. p. 286, although in 
 the latter the sacred money alone is 
 mentioned. 
 
 *7* Corp. Inscript. Gr, No. 160, in 
 his notes to which inscription the 
 author makes the following remark : 
 *' Quod vero templum adhuc superstes 
 idem est atque illud, de quo nostra 
 
 inscriptio, inde non colligitur id tem- 
 plum Olymp. 93,3, non esse incensum. 
 Non enim absumptiim igne dicitur, sed 
 correptum (ad quod non satis attendi 
 (Ec. Civ. Ath. iii. 20,) et recte Vis- 
 contus (de Elgin, p. 113,) judicat, in 
 opere lapideo non potuisse nisi siipel- 
 lectilem et tectum incendio deleri, ut 
 Pantheon Agrippoe post incendiuni 
 adhuc manet." — A^'ol. i. p. 264. 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. Hellen. i. 6, 1. 
 
 *'^ Antiquities of Athens, vol. ii. 
 p. 4 sqq.
 
 442 
 
 HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. [bK. III. 
 
 Minerva Polias ; nor indeed was any treasure laid by before the 
 Persian war, for the first time at which any such deposit was 
 made was after the transfer of the office from Delos ; unless we 
 give this name to the sacred possessions under the management 
 of the treasurers, which were preserved at Athens before it was 
 taken by Xerxes. It is therefore necessary to suppose that the 
 opisthodomus of the Parthenon is meant, in which the treasure 
 was deposited ever after the building of that temple. The 
 opisthodomus as the place of custody for the treasure occurs in 
 an inscription"", which I cannot err materially in assigning to 
 the 90th Olympiad; and at this time the Parthenon alone was in 
 existence, the temple of Minerva Polias not having been as yet 
 built. It should also be remarked, that in addition to the 
 public monies, treasure belonging to temples was deposited in 
 this building''^ and also many valuables: others were kept 
 in the body of the Parthenon itself, as is proved by several 
 inscriptions"^ 
 
 Other precious articles were preserved in different temples ; 
 among which was perhaps the temple of Diana upon the Acro- 
 polis, if the opisthodomus mentioned in an inscription'^" can be 
 referred to this temple. The separate treasure of Minerva 
 Polias^^^ was a portion of the public treasure, which name may 
 have given occasion to the error of the Scholiast to Aristo- 
 phanes. It is unnecessary to inquire in what place the public 
 monies were kept, when the opisthodomus of the Parthenon 
 was burned down in the age of Demosthenes, for there can be 
 no doubt that it was soon afterwards restored'^*. The key of 
 the public treasure and the superintendence of all the monies 
 of the state, belonged to the daily epistates of the prytanes*°\ 
 
 ^'^ Coi-p. Inscript. No. 76. 
 
 57« Ibid. 
 
 ^'^ lb. Nos. 139, 141, 150, 151. 
 
 5^0 lb. No. 150, § 45, cf. § 27. In 
 the temple of Minerva Polias there 
 were also certain precious articles, 
 €. g. in the time of Pausanias the 
 silver-footed stool of Xerxes and the 
 golden sabre of Mardonius (Pausan. i. 
 27). 
 
 •'^' Corp, Inscript. No. 147, Pryt. i. 
 which inscription is of Olymp. 92, 3, 
 (B.C. 410). 
 
 *^* Demosth. c. Timocrat. ubi sup. 
 and Ulpian. 
 
 *^* See the passages of Pollux, Sui- 
 das, and Eustathius ap. !Meins. Cecrop. 
 20. The argument to Demosth. c. 
 Androt. p, 500, 21, speaks of the keys 
 of the Acropolis. Tlie following arti-
 
 CH. XX.] HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. 443 
 
 But the treasurers of the goddess and of the gods had also 
 the right of opening and shutting the doors of the opistho- 
 domus^^\ 
 
 It cannot be proved that any treasure was ever laid by at 
 Athens before the time of Pericles ; and as prior to the period 
 of Themistocles all the money received from the mines was 
 divided among the citizens, it is manifest that they never 
 thought of making any deposit : besides which it would have 
 been impossible for Athens to collect any large amount of trea- 
 sure without the aid of tributary allies. We do not hear of the 
 public treasure until after the transfer of the funds of Delos to 
 Athens ; but when formed, its amount was very large as com- 
 pared to the price of commodities, and it produced considerable 
 benefit to the state. Although its operation may have been so 
 far mischievous, that it took a large quantity of coin out of cir- 
 culation, this evil was more than compensated by the conse- 
 quent lowness of prices, and the power of procuring much with 
 a small outlay of money. At the time when the treasure was 
 brought to Athens, this fund had been in existence about ten 
 years; consequently the sum paid into it could not have exceeded 
 4 600 talents ; a considerable portion of which must have been 
 again disbursed in time of war. Diodorus*^^ is therefore unde- 
 serving of any credit, when he states that nearly 8000 talents 
 were transferred from Delos to Athens: and speaks more 
 absurdly in another place of 10,000 or more*^^; in forming 
 which statements he has evidently confounded other data which 
 were alien to the subject. According to Isocrates^^'', Pericles 
 brought 8000 talents into the Acropolis exclusively of the 
 sacred money. The number 7900, which Pausanias appears to 
 adopt*®% is perhaps more accurate. If this statement is correct, 
 the sum which was transferred from Delos to Athens cannot 
 have exceeded 1800 talents. For there can be no doubt that 
 the public treasure in the time of Pericles, which was formed of 
 
 cle also belongs to this subject, Lex. | '^^^ xii. 38. 
 Seg. p. 188, 22, (TnaTaTrjs : (jjvKa^ tS)v 
 Koivcov ;(pJ7ftarcoi' kol eTriTTjprjTTjs Ta>v 
 
 '^* Corp. Inscript. No. 76. 
 
 '^^ xii. 54, xiii. 21. 
 
 ^'7 ^vfifiaX' 40. 
 
 ^^'^ See note 508, chap. W.
 
 444 HISTORY OF THE PL'BLIC TREASURE. [bK. III. 
 
 the funds transferred from Delos, and whatever was subsequently 
 added to these, amounted, when at the highest, to 9700 talents 
 of coined silver^^°; which number is inaccurately stated by 
 Isocrates and Diodorus to have been 10,000'"^ Demosthenes"^ 
 reckons that during the forty-five years' ascendancy of Athens 
 before the Peloponnesian war, more than 10,000 talents were 
 brought into the Acropolis: and his statement is perfectly accu- 
 rate, for he includes the uncoined gold and silver, of w^hich we 
 will presently speak. At the beginning of this war, the treasure 
 had undergone a considerable diminution from the expenses 
 incurred in building the propyleea and the siege of Potidsea: and 
 according to Thucydides there was only a surplus of 6000 
 talents, from which in Olymp. 87, 2 (b.c. 431), a separate trea- 
 sure of 1000 talents was laid by, together with 100 vessels which 
 W'Cre only to be made use of in case that Attica w^as threatened 
 by a hostile fleet^^^ The large expenses of the following years 
 until Olymp. 88, 1, evidently consumed the whole treasure with 
 the exception of this deposit; especially the enterprises of the 
 last-mentioned year*"; and hence about the winter of this 
 same year it was found necessary to levy a war tax of 200 
 talents for the purpose of defraying the expenses of the siege of 
 Mytilene^^S It w^as not until after the peace of Nicias that the 
 Athenians re-commenced the formation of a treasure, the 
 tributes having at that time been considerably increased, and 
 
 ^^^ Thiicyd. ii. 13. lamis and Platsea in 01}Tnp. 75, i, and 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. Symmach. 2'S, Diod. xii. Olymp. 93, 4, which is 70 years in 
 40. : roinid numbers. Andocides (de Pace, 
 
 59' Olynth. iii. p. 35, 6, and thence p. 107) reckons 85 yeai-sfor the grow^ 
 in the spurious oration Trepi o-vi/rd|eco$-, ing power of Athens, i.e. evidently 
 p. 174, 2. He reckons from Olymp. [ from the battle of Marathon in Olymp. 
 75, 3, until Olymp. 87, 1, since he 72, 3, until Olymp. 94, J, wliich is not 
 speaks of their hegemouia while re- i indeed what one would expect from the 
 cognised by the Greeks, which did not context of his narration. 65 years is the 
 last longer. Isocrates in the Pane- most correct statement ; see Dodwell 
 gyric reckons 70, and in the Panathe- Annal. Thucyd. under Olymp. 77, ^. 
 naic t*5 years; Demosthenes in the [See Clinton, Fast. Hell. vol. ii. Ap- 
 third Philippic 73 years for the dura- ; pend. vi. — Transl.] 
 tiou of the ascendancy of Atliens, all ^^^ See book ii. ch. 23. 
 according to different views. 7^ years i "^ Thucyd. iii. I7. 
 intervened between the battles of 8a- ^"^ Thucyd. iii. 19.
 
 CH. XX.] HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. 445 
 
 such extraordinary preparations for war having ceased to he 
 necessary. 
 
 Andocides in the speech Trepl elprjvrjs and ^schines*", 
 wishing to recommend the adoption of peace, exhaust them- 
 selves in the enumeration of the advantages which Athens had 
 always derived from it: and either with intentional perversion 
 or from ignorance of the ancient history of their country, they 
 so mix together all facts and seasons, that it is no easy task to 
 elicit the truth from such a tissue of confused statements. The 
 following is the substance of what they say on the subject of 
 the public treasure, which is given with no alteration except in 
 the chronological arrangement. 
 
 In the thirty years' armistice or peace between Athens and 
 Sparta, which was only kept for the fourteen years between the 
 ^ginetan (Olymp. 83, 3, b.c. 446) and Peloponnesian wars*-°, 
 1000 talents were deposited in the treasury, which according to 
 law were to be laid by separately {i^aipera) : 100 triremes were 
 added to the navy^®^, and several other preparations made: this 
 however manifestly took place in the first part of the war, and 
 not in the beginning of the peace, as has been already shown""; 
 which makes it more singular that this point should have been 
 dwelt upon by the orators, as it would have far better suited 
 their purpose to mention how much Pericles had collected 
 during that time. They also state that during the peace of 
 Nicias (which was concluded in Olymp. 89, 3, b.c. 422, for 
 fifty years, but was never regularly kept, and in the seventh 
 year, Olymp. 91, 1, b.c. 416, was completely broken by the 
 invasion of Sicily), until Athens upon the persuasion by the 
 Argives again commenced the war, the sum paid into the Acro- 
 polis amounted to 7000 talents"^ Nothing farther is known 
 with regard to the exact amount of the sum, but the statement 
 
 *^^ Andocid. p. 91 sqq. iEschiu. de his statement of this point. The alte- 
 
 Fals. Leg. p. 334 sqq. ration of 1000 into 2000 talents pro- 
 
 ^^^ Diodorus in this year, and there posed by Scaliger is equally aibitrary 
 
 Wesseling, Thucyd. ii. 2, Plutarch, and false. 
 
 Pericl. 24. ^99 Reiske proposes to substitute 
 
 "7 See Andocid. p. 93. 700 for 7000. 
 
 598 Petit iv. 10, 8, is also correct in ,
 
 446 HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. [bK. III. 
 
 appears nevertheless to be deserving of credit. It is not impos- 
 sible that about 1000 talents might have been laid by every 
 year, as the amount of tribute received was so considerable. 
 Thucydides'"° moreover remarks, that during this truce the 
 state had both increased its numbers of men fitted for bearing 
 arms, and again begun to amass treasure. 
 
 Lastly, there can be no doubt that the inscription belongs 
 to this period, in which it is stated that the sacred monies were 
 to be repaid; the 3000 talents which it had been decreed to 
 raise, having been again returned to the Acropolis. Pericles 
 had proposed to the Athenians to make use of the sacred trea- 
 sures in time of necessity, but to replace whatever was borrowed. 
 This perhaps occurred between the 87th and 89th Olympiads: 
 In Olymp. 89, 3, they again began to amass a treasure, and 
 about Olymp. 90, i, 3000 talents had possibly been collected, 
 which sum they then began to think of devoting to the payment 
 of their debts. It is not possible to fix upon any other moment 
 previous to the Anarchy which will accord with this inscription, 
 and it is evident that it belongs to some period before the 
 Anarchy. Those 7000 talents were consumed in the two first 
 years of the Sicilian war, the expenses of this expedition being 
 so enormous that this sum could scarcely have been sufficient 
 to defray them^"\ In the third year of this war there was a 
 most urgent want of supplies; and when subsequently after the 
 defeat in Sicily the revolt of Chios took place (Olymp. 91, 4, 
 B.C. 413), contrary to their law they seized the 1000 talents 
 which had been laid by as the last resource of the state*°^ 
 There can be little doubt that some money must subsequently 
 have been set apart for the public treasure, but it was again 
 immediately disbursed; a subject which might be followed up 
 in all its details, if we were in possession of more complete 
 accounts rendered by the treasurers than the four fragments of 
 inscriptions which still remain*. One of these, of which only a 
 
 coo Yi. 20, a.V€ikTj(pfi rj ttoXis iavrrjv — 
 fs xPVH-^'''^^ (Wpoiaiv. I^Nicias in 
 Thuc. vi. 12, says, aTro voaov fieyaXrjs 
 Kal TToXe/xov ^pax^ ri 'Xe\w(f>7]KafX€v, 
 C0O-T6 KOL xpr]p.a(Ti Koi rots o-copMcnv 
 Tjv^rjaBaL. — Traxsi..] 
 
 •^o- See book ii. ch. 22. 
 
 ^''■^ Thucyd. viii. 15. 
 
 * See class ii. of the Attic Inscrip- 
 tions in the Author's Collection, Nos. 
 137 sqq. — Transl.
 
 CH. XX.] HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. 
 
 447 
 
 few words are wanting, belongs to Olymp. 92, 3 (b.c. 410); 
 another probably to Olymp. 91, 3 (e.g. 414); and the other 
 two are also more ancient than the archonship of Euclid. 
 Aristophanes complains in Olymp. 92, 4 (b.c. 409), that the 
 ancient contributions from the spoils of the Persians were con- 
 sumed, without being replaced by property taxes^''^ The 
 history of the public treasure concludes with the battle of 
 iEgospotamos; subsequently to this engagement Athens appears 
 to haA^e lived chiefly, according to the common saying, from 
 hand to mouth. The passion for the theorica wasted the money 
 that might have been laid by for future wants, and the fre- 
 quency of property taxes proves that the regular revenues were 
 not sufficient. Whoever therefore can suppose that there existed 
 a large treasure at Athens in the time of Lycurgus, must be 
 ignorant of the resources and political condition of Athens at 
 that period. 
 
 It is well known that the public treasure and the temples 
 also contained uncoined gold and silver, of which part was in 
 bars®''^ and part worked up either as vessels or ornaments of 
 the statues. Pericles, as mentioned by Thucydides®"^, states 
 that in the beginning of the Peloponnesian war, there were 
 upon the Acropolis no less than 500 talents of uncoined gold 
 and silver, in public and private ofl'erings, in sacred vessels for 
 the processions and games, in Persian spoil and other similar 
 articles; and he adds, that there was a considerable quantity in 
 the other temples. There were 40 talents of pure gold upon 
 the statue of Minerva, which could be taken oiF: the value of 
 this, according to the lowest estimate, amounted to 400 talents 
 of silver: for it cannot be supposed that these 40 talents were 
 merely estimated in silver^°% as Thucydides expressly speaks of 
 
 «^3 Lysist. 655. 
 
 604 Pqj. which point see Corp. In- 
 script. No. 145. 
 
 «" ii. 13. 
 
 ^"^ This notion has been brought 
 forward bvHeyne (Antiquarische Auf- 
 satze, vol. i. p. 192) as a conjecture, 
 but after the expression of Thucydides 
 
 it appears to me that no doubt can 
 exist. Passing over the Commentators 
 upon this historian, and others who 
 have treated this point in greater length 
 than was required, I only remark that 
 Quatremere de Quincy in his valuable 
 work upon the Olympian Jupiter is of 
 the same opinion which I have adopted.
 
 448 HISTORY OF THE PUBLIC TREASURE. [bK. III. 
 
 gold. Philocliorus however appears to state the quantity of 
 gold more accurately than Pericles as represented by Thucy- 
 dideSj for he mentions the number of 44 talents; which, 
 according to the proportion of 1 to 13, amounts to no less than 
 572 talents of silver. The loss of Polemon's work upon the 
 sacred offerings in the Acropolis^"^ is much to be lamented: in 
 the mean time the catalogue of valuables collected by Meur- 
 sius®**" may be much increased from the accounts preserved in 
 different inscriptions. Lycurgus added many ornaments of 
 this nature, and others were melted down and altered, as for 
 example, crowns and phialse, of which there were many upon 
 the Acropolis^"*. In later times, however, profuse distribution 
 and plunder were not unfrequent: thus we read that Lachares 
 the tyrant stole the ornaments of Minerva and the golden 
 shields. 
 
 Chapter XXI. 
 
 Of the Liturgies in general, and of the Ordinary Ones in 
 particular. 
 
 Hitherto we have only considered what may be strictly called 
 the revenues {irpoaohoi) of the state. The community likewise 
 derived an indirect benefit from the public services or litur- 
 gies (XeLTovpyLai), which saved the state great expenses; 
 although Demosthenes^'" in speaking of another subject observes 
 that the liturgies were not in connexion with the revenue. 
 
 This is the only question within the circle of financial 
 affairs, which has been subjected to an accurate investigation, 
 (viz., by Wolf in his preface to the Oration of Demosthenes 
 against Leptines^'^,) founded upon the testimonies of ancient 
 
 With the statements of Thucydides | Aristoph. Pac. 604, which is the an- 
 
 compare also Plutarch. Pericl. 31, and thority upon which Scaliger proceeds 
 
 de vit. aer. alien. 2. Diodorus (xii. in 'OXv/xtt. 'Ai/ayp. Olymp. 87, 1. 
 40), according to liis custom, mentions ^^'^ See ^leurs. Cecrop. 2. 
 a higher number, viz. 50 talents, as the ^"^ In the same treatise, 
 weight of the gold in the statues, and '"^ Cf. Demosth. c. Androt. p. GIG. 
 compare with this, Siiidas in v. ^eidids. ^"' C. Leptin. § 21. 
 The passage of Philocliorus is in Schol. "" Pp. Ixxxv— cxxv.
 
 CH. XXI.] OF THE LITURGIES IX GENERAL. 
 
 449 
 
 writers. To several points in this dissertation I shall have 
 occasion to refer ; but shall for the most part follow my own 
 course. The errors of my predecessors I shall generally pass 
 over in silence, or only notice them with a few words; and in 
 this I feel less embarrassment with regard to the editor of the 
 Oration against Leptines, as he has subsequently admitted that 
 he has misconceived some parts of this subject^^^ 
 
 The liturgies, as I have already shown*, were not pecu- 
 liar to the Athenians, and they existed among this people from 
 remote times. As early as in the history of Hippias the Pisis- 
 tratid we meet with choregia and hestiasis, the latter under 
 the name of phylarchia; and also the trierarchy^'% which is 
 moreover the foundation of the account of Themistocles havins: 
 provided ships out of the money received from the mines® ^% 
 although the ancient writers do not mention it by name: and 
 the establishment of the Exchange by the law of Solon proves 
 that the liturgies had been introduced even at that early 
 period. 
 
 The word liturgy signifies a service for the community 
 {\y]LTov, \yrov, Xetrov®'*), and also a service performed by a 
 hired servant, or a servant belonging to the state (vTrrjpirr}^, 
 BrjfjLoacos) ; from which it may be inferred, that only services 
 performed in person, such as choregia, trierarchy, &c., were 
 included under the term liturgy, and not the property-tax 
 (elacjiopa), as Heraldus has already remarked^'^ The ancient 
 writers, wherever they speak accurately, distinguish between the 
 liturgies and the property-taxes^ '^ Orphans were exempted 
 
 «^2 Analect. Part i. ad Fin. It is 
 proper that I should remark that my 
 investigations had been long termi- 
 nated before this confession and pro- 
 mise to correct the errors committed 
 were made known. 
 
 * B.iii. c. 1. 
 
 ^•^ See Wolf, p. Ixxxviii. 
 
 "^^ See book iv. ch. 12, also b. i. ch. 
 19, and the dissertation on the Lau- 
 rian mines. 
 
 ^'5 Wolf, p. Ixxxvi. cf. Lex. Seg. p. 
 
 277. AeiTovpyelv is explained by the 
 grammarians els to drjfjiocnov ipyd^ecr- 
 dai, Tco drjfjioaico VTrrjpeTeiv. 
 
 ^'® Anim. in Salmas. Observ. ad I. 
 A. et R. vi. 1, 7. 
 
 ^'^ Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. p. 
 1155, 22, where the trierarchy is in- 
 cluded among the liturgies; cf. p. 
 1146, sup. The same distinction is 
 clearly made by Isocrates Symmach. 
 40, ad fin. and de Antid. p. 80, ed. 
 Orell. 
 
 2 G
 
 450 OF THE LITURGIES IN GENERAL. [bK. III. 
 
 from all liturgies, but not from the property- tax" ^ This then 
 is quite sufficient to show that these two expressions are totally 
 different. Property-taxes were only considered as liturgies 
 when advanced for some other person (7rpo€L(T(f>opd), this being 
 a contribution essentially diflferent from the property-tax itself. 
 Hence Demosthenes' client in the speech against Polycles 
 states that he was not compelled to pay the advance of the 
 property-tax, as he was trierarch, and the law exempted any 
 person from performing two liturgies at the same time^^^ If 
 however the property-tax itself had been considered as a liturgy, 
 all choregi, trierarchs, gymnasiarchs, and other persons serving 
 liturgies, would have been exempted from it, which was evidently 
 not the case. But as the property-taxes have always been in- 
 cluded among the liturgies, even after Heraldus, the explanation 
 of these contradictions has been rendered impossible, and there- 
 fore no writer has willingly touched upon the subject. The 
 ignorant Ulpian^^'^ is the only witness who can be adduced in 
 favour of their identity, and there are some ambiguous expres- 
 sions in the ancient writers which might make it appear that 
 the property-taxes were called liturgies ; but these cannot esta- 
 blish this position; for where there is no precise limitation of 
 the meaning, the word is used to denote every service and 
 every performance of a duty; thus every species of pecuniary 
 aid or expenditure was by an extension of the term called 
 choregia"^ 
 
 With regard to the nature of the liturgies, they may perhaps 
 upon the whole be most aptly compared with the personal ser- 
 vices or contributions in kind of modern days, although the 
 objects were very dissimilar, and the parallel fails also in many 
 other points. The liturgies of the Greeks were likewise con- 
 sidered as a mark of distinction"'; and they were thus produc- 
 tive of public benefit to a degree which could only have been 
 
 •*° See book iv. ch. 1 and 11. j to any object, x^^PT/V^^^ ^**'* Bairdvaf, 
 
 "'» Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1209, 2, 
 see also Oral. c. Phaenipp. p. 1046, 
 20—24. 
 
 ^^ Ad Leptin. § 24, and elsewhere. 
 
 "** Thus it may be said in reference 
 
 &c. 
 
 ^** Aristot. Eth. Nicom. iv. 5. Xe- 
 noph. Off. Mag. Eq. i. 26, Isocrat. 
 Areopag. 20. See Wolf, p. cxvii. note.
 
 CH. XXI.] OF THE LITURGIES IX GENERAL. 451 
 
 possible in the ancient democracies, in which the eflfects of 
 emulation were so powerfully felt; we find indeed that these 
 public servants usually performed more than the law prescribed; 
 and any person who was parsimonious in his expenses exposed 
 himself to popular censure. Another advantage was that the 
 state thus dispensed with the services of many paid officers and 
 contractors ; so that the profit obtained by the latter of these 
 w^as saved to the nation, and neither class received the unfair 
 privileges which are enjoyed by the pubUc functionaries and 
 mercantile speculators of modern days. One disadvantage of 
 the system of liturgies, viz., the tardiness in the naval equip- 
 ments w^hich it occasioned, did not make its appearance until 
 the patriotism of the Athenians had much abated. In the 
 better times all impediments were speedily overcome. But an 
 equable distribution of the burdens was unquestionably a matter 
 of great difficulty; and it frequently happened, that while one 
 person exhausted his means, another made little or no sacrifice, 
 although his property was equally large. And, finally, it fur- 
 nished the citizens with an occasion for ambitious and useless 
 expenditure, and excited them to aim after a pernicious popu- 
 larity"^ Aristotle®^'' justly recommends that expensive and 
 useless liturgies, such as the choregia, lampadarchy, &c., 
 instead of being encouraged, should be not even permitted to 
 those persons who volimtarily undertook to perform them. 
 
 The majority of the liturgies were the ordinary liturgies, as 
 they were called, i,e, returning in a regular succession {iyKVKXioc 
 XeiTovpylac^*^), The trierarchy and the advance of the pro- 
 perty-tax furnish instances of extraordinary liturgies, although 
 we shall not consider the latter in this place, but combine it 
 with the investigation of the tax to which it belongs. There is 
 not any separate name for the extraordinary liturgies; Reiske 
 
 ^^^ Thus the expense of the chore- 
 gia, gymnasiarchy, and trierarchy, was 
 earned to a great extent by Alcibiades. 
 Isocrat. Trept rov (evy. 15. This is the 
 meaning of KaraXeiTovpye^v, Karaxo- 
 priyelv one's property; but a person 
 might KaTa^€vyoTpo<p€'iv and KaOnrno- 
 
 Tp€(f>€2v his estate without performing 
 any public service. 
 
 «^* Polit. V. 8. 
 
 ®-* This expression is thus explained 
 in Lex. Seg. p. 250 : al kut' iviavrov ytvo- 
 p-evaij olov xoprjyiai, yvpLvaaiapxlai. KoL 
 iepcbv Trepiodoi (the architheoria). 
 
 2 G 2
 
 452 OF THE ORDINARY LITURGIES. [bK. III. 
 
 invented the appellation of compulsory liturgies (TrpoaraKral 
 XeiTovpyLai), in order to correct a passage in a Byzantine decree 
 which confers upon the Athenians an exemption from certain 
 liturgies in Byzantium®^^: it is, however, highly improbable that 
 the extraordinary liturgies are intended, for at Athens the extra- 
 ordinary liturgies were the only ones from which an exemption 
 was allowed; and moreover the alteration, even if the extraor- 
 dinary liturgies were meant, must necessarily remain doubtful. 
 
 The most important of the regular liturgies, which we are 
 now about to consider, are the choregia, gymnasiarchy, and 
 feasting of the tribes (ia-rlao-L^;^'''); the archetheoria''* is a 
 fourth, but it is too unimportant to be entitled to a separate 
 discussion, and therefore I may with Wolf pass it over. I need 
 only remark that the latter liturgy was, as well as the trierarchy, 
 considerably lightened by contributions from the public'^^® or 
 sacred treasures®^", which is also asserted by an insignificant 
 ■\mter, of the gymnasiarchy and choregia"'. There were also 
 other liturgies of more rare occurrence, such as the arrephoria 
 and the trierarchy for mock sea-fights, which probably existed 
 only upon extraordinary occasions. And lastly there were cer- 
 tain degrading services performed in the processions by the 
 resident aliens, which belonged to the liturgies. 
 
 The obhgation to render these several services, with the 
 exception only of those last mentioned, was founded upon pro- 
 perty. An estate of 46 minas, or even of 1 or 2 talents, did 
 not entail upon the possessor the performance of any liturgy®^*, 
 although it was sufficient for his maintenance, and made him 
 liable to the payment of property- taxes. The smallest amount 
 of property which obliged the owner to the performance of 
 liturgies, was about 3 talents, unless a person of less wealth 
 voluntarily consented to undergo this burden®^^. Companies 
 
 ^^ Demosth. de Corona, p. 256, 10. ; dias, p. 510, ed. Reisk. 
 
 ^^7 Wolf, p. Ixxxvii. j «32 Is^iis de Hagn. Hered. p. 292, 
 
 ^^^ See the passages quoted by Wolf, 
 p. xc. and frequently in inscriptions. 
 «^9 See book ii. ch. 6. 
 ^^^ See Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 
 (concerning which passage see book i. 
 ch. 20,) Demosth. c. Aphob. i. p. 833, 
 22. 
 
 ^^^ Cases of this kind see in book 
 
 *^^ The anonymous author of the , iv. ch. 15, of the trierarchy, if they are 
 argument to the speech against Mei- really correct.
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 OF THE ORDINARY LITURGIES. 
 
 453 
 
 {crvvreXeiat) did not exist in the regular liturgies"^; except that 
 in Olymp. 92, 1, in the archonship of Callias (b.c. 412), after 
 the national wealth had been exhausted by the Sicilian war, a 
 decree was passed to give permission that two persons might 
 perform the choregia together®". The performer of the liturgy 
 was appointed by his tribe; which shared the fame of victory 
 with the individual, and was therefore inscribed as conqueror 
 upon the tripod. This appointment must have been made 
 according to some regular succession ; yet, if persons willing to 
 undertake the office of choregus were wanting, one individual 
 could serve for two tribes at the same time®^^ The liturgies of 
 the resident aliens were wholly distinct from those of the citi- 
 zens. According to Demosthenes®^^ the ordinary liturgies only 
 required about sixty persons a year; a statement which is hardly 
 credible, since ten hestiatores were necessary for a single feast- 
 ing of the tribes, while for the provision of every kind of chorus 
 there was always the greatest emulation, and every tribe used 
 commonly to furnish a choregus for the sacred feasts®^^, which 
 is equally true of the gymnasiarchy. 
 
 It may be also observed, that if any one who was returned 
 to the state as the performer of a liturgy thought that some 
 other person should be appointed in his stead, he could resort to 
 the legal remedy of the Exchange, as in the case of the trie- 
 rarchy. In order too that no person might be burdened beyond 
 his means, it was enacted by an ancient law, that no one should 
 be bound to perform liturgies for two successive years®^^ 
 Neither was any person forced to perform two liturgies at the 
 same time®^^: w^hence it is evident (as indeed is stated by the 
 orators^^O? that the trierarchs were free from the regular litur- 
 
 «3* Demosth. c. Lept. § 19. 
 
 635 Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 406, to 
 which may be joined Platonius in KUs- 
 ter's Aristophanes, p. xi. 
 
 636 Antiphon de Choreuta, p. 768, 
 Corp. Inscript. No. 216, Demosth. c. 
 Lept. p. 467, 27, and the ancient com- 
 mentators quoted there by Ulpian. 
 
 6^7 c. Lept. § 18, and there Wolf. 
 ^^^ This may be even inferred from 
 
 the passages collected by Sigon. R. A. 
 iv. 9, and is expressly stated by the 
 authors of the arguments to the ora- 
 tion against Meidias, and by Ulpian ad 
 Lept. § 24, in reference to the great 
 Dionysia. 
 
 639 Demosth. c. Lept. § 7 (p. 459, 12, 
 
 ed. Reiske). 
 6^0 Demosth. c. 
 6^' Demosth. c. 
 
 Polycl. p. 1209, sup. 
 Lept. § 16 (p. 462,
 
 454 
 
 OF THE ORDINARY LITURGIES. 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 gies during the time of their trierarchy. Orphans were exempt 
 {areXeh) from all Uturgies for the period of their minority and 
 one year over^*^ Besides this exemption, an immunity from 
 the regular liturgies was also given as a reward or testimonial of 
 honour; and it is to this that Demosthenes refers^''^ when he 
 asserts that there were about five or six citizens, and less than 
 that number of resident aliens, exempted, and that he went to 
 the utmost limit in stating ten. Leptines in Olymp. 106, 1 
 (b.c. 356), carried a law against citizens as well as resident aliens 
 and isoteles possessing an immunity from Uturgies, and even 
 prohibiting that it should ever again be either sought for or 
 granted: but the oration of Demosthenes, which was delivered 
 in the following year, completely put an end to this project^**. 
 
 Chapter XXII. 
 
 TTie Choregia, or furnishing of a Chorus. 
 
 Among the ordinary liturgies which were appointed for the 
 celebration of festivals and the diversion of the people, the 
 choregia must be considered as the most important. 
 
 The office of the choregus was to provide the chorus in all 
 plays, tragic as well as comic {Tpay(pBoL<;, KcjfKpSols) and satyri- 
 cal, and also for the lyric choruses of men or boys, pyrrhi- 
 chistse, cyclian dancers and flute-players (x^piryelv dvBpdcrc or 
 dvhpiKols ')(^opols, rrathiKol^ ')(^opolsy 7rvppL')(^Lo-Ta2<;, kvkXiw %o/)o3, 
 avXrjTac^ avSpdacv), and others. But there is not the least 
 reason for supposing that the choregus defrayed the whole 
 expense occasioned by the play; an error which ought not to 
 
 23), which passage however, accord- 
 ing to the correct interpretation of 
 Wolf, cannot be any longer taken as a 
 proof, and c. Mid. p. 565, 3. That 
 those who served the trierarchies, 
 when they were no longer in the per- 
 formance of this duty, might be called 
 upon to serve other liturgies, is evi- 
 dent, and many instances occur which 
 
 cannot all be attributed to voluntary 
 performance. 
 
 ^*^ Concerning the ateleia in gene- 
 ral see Wolf, p. Ixxi. sqq., book i. ch. 
 15, and where this subject is inciden- 
 tally mentioned, as book iii. ch. 4, 
 book iv. ch. 1, 10, 11. 
 
 «*3 Lept. § 17. 
 
 ^** Die Chrysost. Or. Rhod. xxxi. 
 vol. i. p. 635, ed Reiske.
 
 CH. XXII.] 
 
 THE CHOREGIA. 
 
 455 
 
 have been revived, as it has been lately, after the truth had 
 been pointed out by Heraldus^*^ The state itself contributed 
 largely to the plays, as is proved by several passages in ancient 
 writers; and the lessee of the theatre was also bound to provide 
 for several expenses, in consideration of which he received the 
 entrance-money. If the actors had been provided by the cho- 
 regi, the state would have allotted them to the choregi; but 
 they were allotted to the poets, and not to the choregi^*^; con- 
 sequently the choregus had no concern with them. It is also 
 frequently mentioned that this or that player acted in particular 
 for a certain poet; and moreover the poet taught the actors 
 independently of the choregus; whereas the case was exactly 
 reversed with the teaching of the chorus. The choregi ap- 
 pointed by the tribes were assigned by the archon to the poets, 
 which was called giving a chorus^ *\ 
 
 The first duty of the choregus, after he had assembled his 
 chorus, was to provide a teacher {-xppohihda-Kdkos) to instruct 
 
 ®^' Anim. in Salmas. Observ. ad I. 
 A. et R. vi. 8, 2 sqq. 
 
 ^*^ Hesychius, Suidas, Pliotius in v. 
 v€fjif)(r€is xmoKpiToav. Each poet re- 
 ceived three actors by lot ; and which- 
 ever of them obtained the victory was 
 taken for the next time without a 
 fresh decision. The passage of Plu- 
 tarch. Phoc. 19, from which it might 
 seem that the choregus provided the 
 actors] and their dresses, I have not 
 noticed in the text, as in the first place 
 it is so confused that it is impossible 
 to form any clear notion of the story 
 related there, and secondly because 
 the rpaycdbbs is represented as demand- 
 ing of the choregus what could only 
 have been demanded by the ttoitjttjs, 
 and the rpaycoBos was never the noir]- 
 TT)s, except when the poet appeared as 
 an actor and singer in his own play ; 
 and lastly the whole passage shows 
 that the demand of the tragodus did ! 
 not refer to the character of a queen, 
 which would necessarily be present in ' 
 the play, but only to the KfKocrprjtievai 
 
 TToXXai TToXvTfXaii oTToSot, which the 
 choregus is supposed to have refused ; 
 these however might have been con- 
 sidered by the poet as a chorus, and 
 therefore he may have required the 
 choregus to furnish them with dresses 
 in addition to the chief chorus, and 
 the choregus might refuse to comply, 
 not allowing that these female atten- 
 dants were a chorus, and being only 
 willing to furnish that which he was 
 bound in strictness to supply. Even 
 then if the story is considered as true, 
 it does not prove anything against the 
 supposition of Heraldus. With the 
 exception of this passage it has not 
 however happened to me to meet with 
 anything in favour of the notion that 
 the actors were pro\aded by the cho- 
 regus. 
 
 «*7 Xopov bibovai, with which xopov 
 Xa/Setj/ on the part of the poet corre- 
 sponds. Cf. Plat, de Repub. ii. ad fin. 
 and the Scholiast, and de Leg. vii. p. 
 817, D. Aristoph. Ran. 94, Casaub. ad 
 Athen. xiv. p. 638, F.
 
 456 
 
 THE CHOREGIA, 
 
 [bK. III. 
 
 them in their parts, whom he paid for his trouble. The teachers 
 themselves were proposed, and the choregi received them, as 
 we learn from Antiphon, by lot; which doubtless only means 
 that these lots decided, as was the case in the selection of the 
 flute-player, the order in which the competitors were to choose, 
 as every tribe and choregus would naturally be desirous of 
 having the best^*^: an instance, however, occurs in which the 
 choregus chose a chorodidascalus who was not proposed^ *^ 
 Another duty of the choregus was to provide the singers or 
 musicians who were to receive instruction. In the choruses of 
 boys this service was often connected with great diflSculties, the 
 parents being unwiUing to give up their children, so that the 
 choregi threatened to punish them, or sometimes had recourse 
 to violence""; a license which was necessary in other places as 
 well as Athens: even in the Augustan age the choregi in Stra- 
 tonicea of Caria were allowed full power of forcing children 
 from their parents"\ The apprehension of seduction was the 
 cause of this refusal; for which reason the age prescribed in 
 the laws of Solon for the choregi was upwards of forty years"*; 
 but this regulation had before the Anarchy become a dead letter, 
 even for the choruses of boys. Moreover, the chorus received 
 pay for their services equally with the actors, although it has 
 been supposed without any reason, that the native artists 
 obtained no remuneration"^ The Athenian people were as 
 well paid as foreigners for dancing, singing, and running"^ 
 The choregus was bound to provide such liquid and soHd foods 
 as had the effect of strengthening the voice"^, as long as his 
 chorus continued in existence, and generally he had to maintain 
 
 «^3 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 519, Aris- 
 topli. Av. 1404, Antiphon de Clioreuta, 
 p. 767, 768, cf. Petit iii. 4, 2. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Mid. p. 533. 
 
 ®*' Antiphon ut sup. 
 
 "' Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 2715. 
 
 "* TEschin. c. Timarch. p. 391. 
 
 «53 Wolf, p. xciii. note. 
 
 "* Xenoph. de Republ. Ath. i. 13. 
 
 «" Phitarch de Glor. Ath. C. An- 
 tiph de Choreuta, and the argument 
 
 of the same speech. Concerning the 
 maintenance of the choinis see also the 
 anonymous author of the argument to 
 Demosthenes against Meidias, and 
 Ulpian ad Lept. § 24. In Corcyra also 
 (and it was no doubt the same every- 
 where) the chorus and the musicians 
 were pro^•ided with maintenance in 
 money or in kind (ainjpeaia) ; see 
 Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 1845.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE CHOREGIA. 457 
 
 the chorus during the period of their instruction. For the 
 representation itself he furnished (in the same manner that the 
 archetheori provided the ornaments) the sacred clothes adorned 
 with gold for the use of himself and of the chorus, golden 
 crowns''', and the masks of the chorus, and any articles of a 
 similar description which were required at the performance of 
 the play. The choregus was also bound to supply a place for 
 the school either in his own house or elsewhere'". Additional 
 persons were required for subordinate offices. Thus Antiphon^s 
 client provided four men for the management of the chorus, of 
 whom one was appointed solely for the purchase of whatever 
 the teacher considered useful for the boys. Any person who 
 did not supply the legal amount was reprimanded by the 
 proper authorities'^^ 
 
 From this account it is manifest that the choregia must 
 have occasioned a considerable expense, though differing ac- 
 cording to the nature of the representation. The chorus of 
 flute players cost more than the tragic chorus'" j whence it is 
 evident that the choregus did not defray the expenses of the 
 whole play: and the comic chorus cost less than the tragic; it 
 was indeed considered vulgar to provide expensive dresses of 
 gold, purple, and ornaments of a similar kind for the former"". 
 Demosthenes"', mentioning the donation which the people had 
 made to Lysimachus the son of Aristides, says, that any person 
 would sooner receive the third part of it than immunity from 
 the liturgies. The gift was consideral)le; but we are too little 
 acquainted with the value of landed property in Euboea to 
 determine with certainty what amount of income he derived 
 from it. At the same time I do not imagine that the third part 
 of his income accruing from this donation amounted to more 
 than 1200 drachmas; and consequently the average yearly 
 expense of the ordinary liturgies could scarcely have amounted 
 to so large a sum, on the supposition that the person serving 
 
 656 Demosth. c. Mid. pp. 519, 520, 658 XenopL. Hier. 9. 4. 
 
 531, Antiphanes ap. Athen. iii. p. 103 j '^9 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 505, 6. 
 
 F. Ulpian ut sup. cf. Herald, ut sup. 5. | ^''^ Herald, vi. 8, 5. 
 
 657 Antiphon in the above-cited j "^ Demosth. c. Lept. § 95. 
 speech.
 
 458 
 
 THE CHOREGIA. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 them only expended the precise sum required, or a little over^ 
 Aristophanes^^*, as we learn from Lysias, had in the space of 
 four or five years, for himself and his father, spent 5000 
 drachmas upon two tragic choregias, three years of which time 
 he was also trierarch. This evidently exceeded the standard 
 fixed by law. 
 
 A brilliant example of an excessive expenditure is also 
 afforded by another client of the same orator^®\ This person 
 had been choregus in his eighteenth year, in the archonship of 
 Theopompus (Olymp. 92, 2, b.c. 411) after the scrutiny {Sokc- 
 fiaala), and had given 3000 drachmas for a tragic chorus. In 
 the same year, after an interval of three months, he paid 2000 
 drachmas for a chorus of men, with which he was victorious. 
 In the year which immediately followed, in the archonship of 
 Glaucippus (Olymp. 92, 3, b.c. 410), he gave 800 drachmas for 
 a chorus of beardless pyrrhichistae at the great Panathensea; and 
 in the same year, at the great Dionysia, 5000 drachmas for a 
 chorus of men, with which he again obtained the victory; and 
 was thus exposed to the farther expense of consecrating the 
 tripod, which was commonly set up in a cell distinguished by an 
 inscription. Immediately afterwards in the archonship of Dio- 
 des (Olymp. 92, 4, B.C. 409), he paid 300 drachmas for a cyclic 
 chorus at the little Panatheneea; data from which we also get 
 the proportion between the expenses of the different per- 
 formances. This same individual was trierarch for the seven 
 years from Olymp. 92, 2, to Olymp. 93, 4 (b.c. 411— 405), at 
 an expense of 6 talents; and at this same time, although absent 
 on his duties as trierarch, he paid two property-taxes, one of 
 3000, the other of 4000 drachmas: in the archonship of Alexias 
 (Olymp. 93, 4, b.c. 405) he was gymnasiarch at the Promethea, 
 and was the victorious competitor, at an expense of 1200 
 drachmas: a chorus of boys cost him soon afterguards more than 
 1500 drachmas: and in the archonship of Euclid (Olymp. 94, 
 2, B.C. 403) he conquered with a comic chorus, upon which he 
 
 "^^ Lysias pro Aristoph. bon. p. 642, 
 cf. p. 633. 
 
 "3 'AttoX. ScopoS. p. 698 sqq. Petit 
 Leg. Att. iii. 4, 1, has treated this pas- 
 
 sage with his usual ill luck, for which 
 he has been sufficiently censured by 
 others.
 
 CII. XXII.] THE CHOREGIA. 459 
 
 expended 1600 drachmas, including the ornaments and dresses 
 which were consecrated; in addition to which he paid 700 
 drachmas for a chorus of beardless pyrrhichistae at the Uttle 
 Panathensea. He conquered with his trireme in a mock sea 
 fight off Sunium, at an expense of 1500 drachmas: and more- 
 over he consumed above 3000 drachmas upon arrhephoria, 
 architheoria, &c. The sum of his expenses in nine years 
 amounts precisely to 10 talents 36 minas. 
 
 This person unquestionably made great sacrifices; but, in 
 order to avoid making any false estimate of the public burthens, 
 it must be clearly understood that, whatever was his motive, 
 whether ambition, or a desire of obtaining distinction by the 
 liberal application of a large fortune, he performed more than 
 was required of him : the possibility of any exaggeration in the 
 sums I will leave entirely out of the question. In the first 
 place he was not bound to serve any liturgies in the first year 
 after the scrutiny : he was not bound to perform several ordi- 
 nary liturgies in the same year: he was not bound to devote 
 himself to them several years without interruption : he was not 
 bound to perform ordinary liturgies at the same time with a 
 trierarchy, the latter being a ground of exemption from the 
 former : nor was he bound to be trierarch for seven years, a 
 service to which no person was oftener liable than once in three 
 years®®*: and indeed after the trierarchy he was for one year 
 allowed an exemption from all liturgies. In short, this person 
 does not in the least exaggerate when he asserts, that legally he 
 need not have subjected himself to a fourth part of the expenses 
 which he actually incurred. Assuming however that he was 
 legally liable to the fourth part, which amounts to nearly 160 
 minas, it must not be forgotten that out of the nine years seven 
 were burthened with the current expenditure of a war, for which 
 two property-taxes were raised, amounting alone to more than 
 70 minas ; and that the years of peace were still more unpro- 
 pitious; and again, that his property must have been very 
 considerable, as may be seen from the amount of his expenses, 
 and above all from the long duration of his trierarchy. We 
 
 Avo cTtj KUTaXiTTcou, IssBUS de ApoUod. Heied. p. 184.
 
 460 
 
 THE CHOREGIA. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 III. 
 
 may therefore fairly assume, without any danger of exaggeration, 
 that his estate amounted to 20 talents : the inheritance of 
 Demosthenes, by which the possessor was bound to perform 
 the trierarchy, amounted to 15 talents : many other persons 
 were however possessed of double, triple, or many times that 
 sum. If then we assume this amount, Aristophanes must upon 
 an average have paid 1 7f minas a year from an estate of 20 
 talents; or, reckoning in our money, 71^' from a property of 
 4833/. 
 
 If this should appear a heavy taxation, I answer that it is 
 precisely the same as if a citizen in modern days were not only 
 to pay nothing in the shape of taxes, but were to receive in 
 addition to this property an annual donation of about 200/. 
 For if we only reckon 18 (4350/.) out of the 20 talents as pro- 
 ductive capital, the average rate of interest being 12 per cent., 
 the possessor must have had an income of rather more than 2 
 talents or 120 minas (483/.) a year; of which he did not pay the 
 seventh part to the public: 'whereas at the present time an 
 estate of 4350/. bearing interest does not produce on an average 
 more than an income of 215/., and from the excessive lowness 
 of prices the means of enjoyment which the remaining six- 
 sevenths of his income would have afforded w^ould have been 
 very great. Thus the marvel of the enormous taxes paid by 
 the Athenian citizens is readily accounted for; in order to show 
 which I have taken into consideration the whole passage of 
 Lysias, including that part which does not relate to the choregia. 
 Every age must be judged from itself; what appears incompre- 
 hensible in one, is in another perfectly natural*. 
 
 By the unfortunate termination of the Peloponnesian war 
 (Olymp. 93,4, B.C. 405), and the dominion of the thirty tjTants, 
 the internal prosperity of Athens received as severe a shock as 
 her foreign power, through the decline of house-rent and trade, 
 and the loss of all foreign landed property. It is therefore easy 
 to understand why, when Aristophanes represented the ^olo- 
 
 * Compare the passage of Antiphanes 
 Atheii. iii. p. 103, where the expenses 
 of the choi'egus are thus described : 
 
 *H x^pvyos alpedels 
 pcLKOi (fiopel. — Transl.
 
 CH. XXII.] THE CHOREGIA. 461 
 
 sicon and the second Plutus (Olymp. 97, 4, B.C. 389), there 
 should have been no choregi for the comic chorus^", although 
 persons were found to fill this office in the archonship of Euclid 
 (Olymp. 94^ 2, b.c. 403). The parabasis disappeared from the 
 comedy from another reason: after which the chorus only 
 remained as an acting or interlocutory character^ as it appeared 
 in the second Plutus and in the new comedy, particularly in 
 Menander. This is doubtless the abolition of the choregia, 
 which the Scholiast to Aristophanes^®^ states to have been 
 effected by Cinesias, on account of the censure he had received 
 from comic poets. Comedy however did not cease with the 
 cessation of the chorus, which is a fresh proof that the choregus 
 provided no part of the performance but the chorus. Demos- 
 thenes in the oration against Leptines*'^ does not apprehend 
 any want of choregi: but his own speeches, and even some 
 circumstances of his own life, prove that in the 106th Olympiad 
 (the effects of the social war having probably been still in opera- 
 tion), the full number of choregi could not be procured. The 
 tribe Pandionis had supplied no choregus for three years, until 
 a dispute having arisen between the archon and the managers of 
 the tribes, Demosthenes voluntarily undertook the choregia''^ 
 In Olymp. 127, 2 (b.c. 271), we even find the state performing 
 the part of choregus for the tribes Pandionis and Hippothontis, 
 and it was moreover victorious in both instances, in the chorus 
 of boys and men®®^ 
 
 Chapter XXIII. 
 
 The Gymnasiarchy, or Provision of Sacred Games : the Hestiasis, 
 or Feasting of the Tribes. 
 
 The gymnasiarchy was, in the time of the Roman emperors, 
 performed at Athens by gymnasiarchs, whose office sometimes 
 lasted for a year, and sometimes for twelve or thirteen months. 
 
 ^" 'ETre'XiTTOv ol x^^PVy^h Platonius j ®" Ubi sup. 
 de Comoedia, p. 11, Aristoph. Vit. p. j ''^ Demosth. c. Mid. pp. 578, 579. 
 14, with regard to the expression see Decree i. at the end of the Lives of 
 Demosth. in Lept. § 18. i the Ten Orators. 
 
 666 ijan. 406. ' ^^^ Corp. Inscript. Gr. Nos.225, 226.
 
 4j62 
 
 THE GYMNASIARCHY. 
 
 [bk. IIT. 
 
 who had the superintendence and care of the training schools, 
 and the exercises performed under the instructions of the 
 teachers {yvfivaaral, 7ratSoT/3ty8at)"". With the later gymna- 
 siarchy we are only acquainted from inscriptions. The annual 
 gymnasiarchs, however, at that time provided for the sacred 
 games which were performed by the gymnasts, the lampade- 
 phoria for example'^'. There is no reason for supposing that 
 the ancient gymnasiarchs, with whom alone we have any con- 
 cern, ever had the superintendence of the training schools. 
 Ulpian^^*^ alone asserts that the gymnasiarchs were bound to 
 supply a full crater of oil to such persons as wished to anoint 
 themselves at the public expense: but it may be at once per- 
 ceived with what ease this negligent writer may have seized 
 upon some fact, and generalized what only held good of later 
 times. Or even if the statement did refer to an earUer period, 
 it was perhaps limited to those who were training for the sacred 
 games. We therefore make a distinction, which has not always 
 been sufficiently attended to, between the modern and ancient 
 gymnasiarchy, and limit the latter to the superintendence of the 
 sacred games. 
 
 We have now to ascertain what were the expenses of the 
 gymnasiarch. He provided the oil, we are told upon the 
 authority of Ulpian, a statement which I do not object to, 
 although we learn from inscriptions that the oil was furnished 
 to the gymnasiarchs in several places in ancient Greece, and 
 even in Athens at the time of Hadrian; and that in many 
 periods none but particular gymnasiarchs supplied the oil 
 voluntarily^^'. Wolf conjectures that they also furnished the 
 dust, and it is very possible that such was the practice. There 
 is however another more important fact which we know without 
 
 ^70 Van Dale, Dissert, ad Marm. p. 
 584 sqq. 
 
 *'7' Inscript. ap. Gruter, p. 317, 3 
 (Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 243), 79, 6 
 (and elsewhere in single passages), 
 concerning which comp. Biagi Monum. 
 Gr. et Lat. ex Mus. Nan. p. 43 sqq. 
 
 «72 Ad Lept. § 24. 
 
 ®7^ Instances of which are furnished 
 by the well-known Sicilian inscription 
 concerning the oil for the gymnasia, 
 the ordinance of Hadrian with regard 
 to the duty upon and the exportation 
 of oil (Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 355), 
 and the decree of the Salaminians, 
 ibid. No. 108.
 
 CH. XXIII.] THE GYMNASIARCHY. 463 
 
 the aid of conjecture, viz., that the gymnasiarchs were bound to 
 maintain and pay those persons who were training for the cele- 
 bration of the festivals'^*: a burthen by no means inconsider- 
 able, as the combatants required the most nourishing foods. 
 The cost of ornamenting the place of combat for the festival, 
 together with many other expensive preparations, doubtless 
 also fell upon the gymnasiarch. 
 
 The lampadarchy, as being a particular species of the 
 gymnasiarch y, deserves to be mentioned' ^\ The lampade- 
 phoria on foot was a common solemnity; it was performed on 
 horseback in the time of Socrates for the first time at Athens'^'. 
 The art consisted in running fastest without extinguishing the 
 torch: a feat in which there is no difficulty with the pitch- 
 torches of modern days, but not easily performed with the 
 waxen lights borne by the competitors, which were secured in 
 a species of candlestick protected by a shield, as we learn from 
 monuments of ancient art now extant. It is possible too that 
 it was necessary to illumine the course, as the race took place 
 at night. Games of this kind were only celebrated to the gods 
 of fire; and five of them were held at Athens, one at the 
 Hephaestea, the presiding deity of which was also worshipped 
 at the Apaturia by men in sumptuous dresses, holding in their 
 hands torches which they lighted at the sacred hearth in token 
 of thanks for the use of fire; another at the Promethea in the 
 exterior ceramicus in the Academy; another at the Panathenaea, 
 perhaps however only at the great Panathenaea; manifestly 
 because Minerva, as being the goddess of arts and companion 
 of Vulcan, was also goddess of fire; she was also honoured at 
 Corinth with the lampadephoria""; at the Bendidea, in which 
 
 '7* Xenoph. de Rep. Ath. 1, 13, de 
 Vectig. 4, 52 
 
 «75 Aristot. Polit. V. 8. 
 
 "'« Plat, de Rep. init. Its diflferent 
 names are Xa/zTras-, Xa/iTraST^Spo/xia, 
 \afX7ra8T]({)opiay XafxTraBovxos dyoiv. See 
 Meurs. Grsecia Feriata, Castellan, de 
 Fest. Grsec. Van Dale ut sup. p. 504, 
 
 sqq. Schneider ad Xenoph. de Vec- 
 tig. p. 170. 
 
 ^7^ Harpocration in v. Xa/x7ray, and 
 there Valesius, Suidas in v. \afind8os, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 277, Aristoph. Ran. 1119, 
 and the Scholiast, also Schol. Ran. 131. 
 Concerning the lampadephoria in ho- 
 nour of Vulcan as a Grecian custom. 
 
 Caylus Recueil d'Antiq. T. I. p. 17 ! see also Herod, viii. 98, of Prometheus
 
 464 
 
 THE GYMNASIARCHY. 
 
 [bk. III. 
 
 Diana Benclis appears in the character of goddess of the 
 moon"^: and lastly, at the annual games of Pan the god of 
 fire^'^ 
 
 For all these spectacles the gymnasiarchs had to provide : 
 and, as considerable emulation existed, one person was ap- 
 pointed from each tribe for every game, whether accompanied 
 or not with lampadephoria^®". The gymnasiarchy was not by 
 any means one of the inferior liturgies. A cyclic chorus, or a 
 chorus of pyrrhichistee, appears to have been generally less 
 expensive. x\n inscription of the tribe Pandionis, of the time 
 immediately succeeding the thirty tyrants, mentions the con- 
 querors in the gymnasiarchy for the Promethea and the He- 
 phsestea, together with those who had conquered at the Thar- 
 geha and Dionysia with a chorus of men or boys. The tribe 
 confers the same honour upon the one as upon the other^^^ 
 Iseeus®^^ classes the gymnasiarchy for lampadephoria with the 
 trierarchy, the property-taxes in the class of the three hundred, 
 and the tragic choregia. Aristotle includes it, together with 
 the choregia, among the expensive and useless liturgies: Alci- 
 biades and Nicias, who w^ere distinguished for their great 
 expenses upon public liturgies, performed the gymnasiarchy®^^ 
 
 Pausan. i. 30, at Corinth in honour of 
 ^linerva Schol. Find. Olymp. xiii. 56. 
 That the Panathenaic lampadephoria 
 was only celebrated at the great Pana- 
 thensea may perhaps be inferred from 
 the anonymous author of the argument 
 to the oration against Meidias, p. 510, 
 as he states that gjinnasiarchs were 
 only appointed for the great festival. 
 Into the inaccuracy of this limitation 1 
 shall not now however inquire. A 
 gymnasiarch of the tribe Cecropis oc- 
 curs in a mutilated inscription, Corp. 
 Inscript. Gr. No. 251. 
 
 ^'^ Plat, ubi sup. The lampade- 
 phoi-ia in this passage has indeed been 
 referred to the less Panathensea, which 
 would fall immediately after the Ben- 
 didea ; Corsini has however shoAvn that 
 the less as well as the gi'eat Panathe- 
 
 nsea were celebrated in the month 
 Hecatombaeon, and consequently are 
 here out of place. See the above-cited 
 inscription. 
 
 «79 Herod, vi. 105, Phot, in v. Xa/x- 
 Tras, and Lex. Seg. ubi sup. 
 
 680 Argum. ad Mid. ut sup. In the 
 Lex. Seg. ubi sup. the yvfivaaiapxoi 
 are simply called ol apxovres twv Xa/x- 
 nadodpofjiicop, which explanation is too 
 confined. 
 
 ^^^ Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 213. 
 
 ®^" Isgeus de Philoctem. Ilered. p. 
 154, where the expression made use of 
 is yvfj-vacTLapxelv Xapwddi, with which 
 comp. Xenoph. de Vectig. ut sup. eV 
 Tois XafiTrdcn yvp,vaaiapxovix(voi. 
 
 ^^^ Isocrat. nepl rov (evy. 15, Plu- 
 tarch. Nic. et Crass. 2.
 
 CH. XXIII.] THE HESTIASIS. 465 
 
 The client of Isaeus in the speech for the inheritance of Apollodo- 
 rus*^* boasts of his honourable gymnasiarchy for the Hephsestea. 
 According to Lysias^^^ a victorious gymnasiarchy for the Pro- 
 methea cost 1200 drachmas. 
 
 The feasting of the tribes (eariaais), a species of liturgy 
 which occurred less frequently, was provided at the expense of 
 particular persons selected from the tribe (iaTidropes), Har- 
 pocration*^® informs us that if no person came forward volun- 
 tarily, some one was appointed by lot; which is stated as if 
 upon the authority of the oration of Demosthenes against Mei- 
 dias, where nothing of the kind occurs. It appears to be an 
 incorrect inference from what is stated in that speech respecting 
 the appointment of the choregi, the voluntary choregia of De- 
 mosthenes, and the order which was determined by lot in the 
 election of the chorodidascalus^^^ The hestiatores were doubt- 
 less appointed, like all persons serving liturgies, according to 
 the amount of their j^roperty, in some regular succession which 
 is unknown to us^^^: for no burthen of this description could 
 have been imposed upon a citizen by lot. The banquets which 
 were provided at this liturgy, were different from the great 
 f eastings of the people, the expenses of which were defrayed 
 from the funds of the theorica. Entertainments at the festivals 
 of the tribes^ ^^ {(jivXerL/ca Selirva) were introduced for sacred 
 objects only, and for the maintenance of a friendly intercourse 
 between the citizens of the tribe, and also from motives agree- 
 
 ^"^ P. 184. This g}-mnasiarcliy is chorus of boys at tlie Dionysia (Corp. 
 also mentioned by Andocides (de Myst. Inscript. Gr. No. 213), and again with 
 65) as having been performed by him, a cyclic chorus (A^'it. Dec. Orat. p. 
 together with the archetheoria to the 229). 
 
 Isthmus and Olympia; and the sanie ^^^ See above, chap. 22. 
 mentions his having gained a victory ^^^ Harpocration in v. ecrru'lTcop. 
 in a lampadephoria, and tlierefore by *'"^7 Demosth. c. Mid. pp. 518, 519. 
 the gymnasiarchy, in his oration against "^^ This is cfiepcLv ia-riaTopa. De- 
 Alcibiades, p. 133, it happened how- mosth. c. Boeot. de Nora. p. 99G, 24. 
 ever earlier. Another victory was The filling the office itself is called 
 also obtained at thePanathenseaby the \ ea-riav ttjv (pyXriv, Demosth. c. Mid. p. 
 same person with an evavdpia, a game \ 565, 10. 
 wliich also belonged to the liturgies j ^^^ Athen. v. p. 185 C. 
 (c. Alcib. ubi sup.) another with a 
 
 2 II
 
 466 THE IIESTIASIS. [l3K. 111. 
 
 able to the spirit of democracy^ ^''. Delicacies were probably 
 never provided; but meat was given at these banquets, as may 
 be collected from Pollux''^'. If we reckon 2000 guests, and the 
 cost of each at 2 oboli, which is probably rather under than 
 above the truth, the expenses of an hestiasis may be estimated 
 at nearly 7^)0 drachmas. 
 
 ' Cf. Herald, ut sup. ii. 1, 12. «^' in. 07-
 
 EniAPXinnOYAPXONTOS^PYNIONOSAHMAPXOY 
 
 [KJATATAAEM ISSOYZINnEIPAIEI ZRA PAA I ANKA I AAM Y P I 
 [A]AKAlTOeHZ El O N KA I T A AAAT EMENHAHA NTATOY ZM I X[G]n 
 [Z]AMENOYZYn EP:A:A P AX M AZ K A e I ZTANA I A ROT I MHM ATH Z M 
 [IJZenZEnZAEIOXPEHNTOYZAEENTOZAAPAXMANErrYNT H 
 [N]AnOAIAOMENONTA EA YTOYTHZMI ZeilZEnZ E H I TO I ZA E M 
 [l]ZeOYZ IN AN En ITIMHTAKAI ATEAHEANAETI ZE I Z<1>0 P A P 
 [IjrNHTAI A nOTil NXnP I IINTOYTIMHMATOZTOYZAHMOT A Z E 
 [l]Z<t>EPEINTHNAEYA IN K A I THN f H NMHEEEZTH E E A T E INTO 
 [Y]ZMIZenZAMENOYZMHTEEKTOYeHZE lOYMHTEE KTXIN A A A 
 nNTEMENilNMHA ETHN YAHNAAn OZHTniXXlPini Ol M I Z[e]n 
 ZAMENOITOeEZMO<l>0 P I O NKA I TOTO YZXO I NOYNTOZ K A I Z 
 AAAAENNOMI ATHNMI ZeXl I NKAT AGH ZOYZ I THNM EN HM IZ 
 EANENTni EKATOMBA I UNITHNAEHM IZEANENTXll ROZ I A E 
 ilN I Ol M IZenZAMENO I RAPAA I ANKA I AAMYP I AAKA ITO O H 
 ZE I ONKAITAAAAE I H O YT I EZTINOZAOIO N T E K A I 9 E M I TO N 
 EZTINEPTAZIMAnOE IN K AT ATAA E E PT AZON T A I T A M E N E 
 N NEAETHOnnZ A N BOYAilNTA ITillAEAEKATIilETHITHNH 
 M IZEANAPOYNKA IMHRAE I AOnnZANTHI M I ZSnZAME Nfll 
 METATAYTAEENI YHEPrAlEZeA I AROTHZE KTHZERIAEK 
 ATOYANSEZTHP inNOZEANAEOAEI flAPOZE I HTHNHM I Z E 
 ANTilNAHMOTflNEZTXlOKAPnOZOnA E IXINTHNO I K I ANTHN 
 ,. ./\.. . lAIZTErOYZANHAPAAABilNKAIOPeHNKATAT* 
 [ desunt litterae xxxii ]N * HNO PG A I 
 
 C
 
 467 
 
 Note [_A],iJ. 307. 
 
 The present inscription was first published by Chandler (ii. 110) from a 
 very inaccurate transcript, together with a Latin vei-sion, and without any 
 attempt at explanation. It was afterwards given by Professor Boeekh, in the 
 Appendix to his Staatshaushaltung (vol. ii. p. 3:i6), where he corrected many 
 of Chandler's errors; and he has since repeated it with some additional 
 improvements in his Collection of Greek Inscriptions (No. 103, vol. i. p. 141; 
 cf. p. 900). As, however, after this last edition some difficulties still remained, 
 which the inaccuracy of the transcript made use of by Mr. Boeekh placed in 
 his way, the translator has thought it desirable to give in the form of a note a 
 more correct copy, made by himself, from the original inscription, which is 
 now preserved in the British Museum (No. 289). 
 
 The inscription consists of twenty -four lines, with the date, which is written 
 in larger characters upon a projecting ledge of the stone, and has thus all its 
 letters perfect, while the first letter of each of the next nine lines is lost. A 
 transverse blow has destroyed tlie first seven letters of the twenty-third line, 
 and nearly all the last line ; the word OPGAI appears, however, to have been 
 the last of the inscription, as a part of the original under surface of the right 
 corner still remains. It is written aroixrjdoVf each of the first fourteen lines, 
 after the date, containing forty-three letters : but in the sixteenth line the 
 stone cutter had written ETIN for E2TIN, and the T was afterwards changed 
 into a 2, the I into a T, and an I was inserted ; so that after the correction, the 
 number of lettei-s is forty-four. The remaining lines contain only forty-two 
 letters. Tliere is no difference between O and 0, and A is frequently put for 
 A. In the vacancies for one letter in the eleventh and thirteenth lines, the 
 surface of the stone appears to be perfectly preserved, and there is no trace 
 of any letter having existed. In the sixteenth line, the nineteenth letter was 
 at first E. Tlie whole inscription may be thus written in modern characters. 
 
 l^Kjard TciSe fjnadovaiv HeLpatels UapaXcav real 'AXfjuvpi- 
 [8] a Kol TO Grjaelov Koi raWa T6/J,evr} airavTa. rovs |lLa[6^^ co- 
 [^a-^afj,evov9 vTrep: A: Spa^/xas KaOiardpac d7roTLfi7]/jLa ttjs fi. 
 5 [t]<T^a)cre&)9 d^LO^pecov^ tov<; Be ivros A Spa'X^ficoy iyyvrjTT}" 
 [y^ dirohiBofievov rd eavrov rrjs pLiaOfjoaecos. iirl rolaBe fi- 
 [^cjadova-LV dveTrirlpji^Ta koI dreKrj. idv he res ela(^opd 7- 
 \_r\'yv7]Tai diro tojv y^wplfov rov ripi.r}pLaTO^^ tovs hi^pboras e- 
 [l^ac^epeiv. rrjv Be vXrjv koi rrjv yrjv p.r) e^earco i^dyeiv ro- 
 10 \_v\9 pbvaOdiaapbevous /x/jre e/c rov drjaetov pbyre i/c rcov dW- 
 
 2 H 2
 
 468 NOTE TO BOOK III. 
 
 cov Te/JL€VQ)V' fjLTjBe rrjv v\7]v **** 00-77 To3 ')(^(0pL(p. ol fita{6)co- 
 
 (JOLfieVOL TO ©€a/jL0(f)6pL0V KoX TO TOV X')(OLVOVVTOS Kat T- 
 
 aWa ivvofJLia ttjv /jLLO-6o){(T)iV KaTaOrjaovat Tr]v f^ev rjfiia- 
 eiav ev tu> 'EKaTO/bL/Satcovc, Trjv he rffMiaetav iv rw ITocrtSe- 
 
 15 covt. ol /jLLaOcoordfievot HapaXlav koI 'AXfjuvplSa koX to ©rj- 
 crelov Kol ToXka el ttov tc eVrtV, oaa olov re Kal OefiLTOv 
 i<rTLV ipydatfjua iroelv, Kara rdBe ipyda-ovTat, tcl fiev e- 
 vvea €T7j oTTft)? av BovXayvTac, to3 8e BeKdT(p eret ttjv r)- 
 lilaeiav dpovv koI /jlt) TrXetco, oircos av rw /j,La6o)aa/xev(p 
 
 20 fjLeTOL TavTa i^fj vTrepyd^ecrdao ajro t^9 eKT7]s iirl BeK- 
 a TOV ^AvOeo-TTjpLCJVos' idv Se TrXela) dpoarj rj ttjv rj/jLLO-ei- 
 
 av, T(OV SlJJJLOTMV €O-T(0 6 KapTTOS 6 TrXeicoV TTjV oiKiav Trjy 
 
 \_iv*A]X\_/jLvp'\lBi, (JTiyovcrav TrapaXa/Scov Kal opdrjv KaTa T\r)- 
 V avvdrjKrjv. iraaaL he at olKiac TrapahchocrOl^cov opOaL 
 
 In the third line, A is supplied from the word 'AX/jivpida in the fifteenth 
 line, where it is written quite distinctly^: 1. 4, ErrYNTH[N], and 1. 20, 
 ESNI, for iyyvrjTrjv and e^fj ; 1. 9, YAIN for vXtjv; 1. 12, 2 for T (raXXa 
 (vvofiia^y as in 1. 3, rciWa refievrj anavra, and 1. 16, TciWa e'i ttov tl eariv) ; 
 1. 5, APAXMAN for dpaxi^cov; 1. 19, nAEIA for nXeico ; and 1. 18, ETHI for 
 cTfi, are apparently mere eiTors of the engraver : but fjfiiaeav in 1. 14 and 19, 
 TToaideayvi in 1. 14, noe'iv in 1. 17, and dpoacL in 1. 21, are probably intentional. 
 
 The only difficulty is caused by the word which succeeds vXrjv in the 
 eleventh line. The sense appears to require the infinitive mood of a verb 
 signifying to damage, or to cut, or some equivalent expression. 'A/xav has the 
 proper number of letters, but the letter which follows the second A appears to 
 be i2 K In the twenty-first line also, the sense seems to require dpoaocxrc for 
 dpoaj] ; but the participle napaXa^cov is evidently meant to refer to one 
 person. Perhaps the chief tenant occupied the house in HalmjTis. The 
 word in the twenty-third line, which Chandler could not read, is updfjp ; the 
 
 ^ Lex. ap. Bekk. Anecd. p. 383, 16, ^AXpLvpides: tottos tis nepl ras eaxarias 
 TTJs ^ArriKfji. ^ Api(TTO(pdvT]S Trjpcl (f. TrjpaL) 
 
 edei be ye ere ^XrjBelcrav els aXfivpidas 
 TTjdl piTj napexeip ye Trpay/zara. 
 
 * The word ewopnov is rendered in the text by pasture-land, according to 
 the last explanation of the author in his work on Inscriptions. It is used in 
 a slightly difi"erent sense to signify a fee for pa^turinc/, in an Orchomenian 
 inscription. (Corp. Inscript. Grsec. No. 1569; and see Boeckh's note, vol. i. 
 page 743.) 
 
 ^ The author has suggested two different methods of explaining this passage ; 
 but they afford no assistance, as he was not aware that it was necessary to 
 supply a letter.
 
 NOTE TO BOOK III, 469 
 
 letters are, however, quite distinct : the last word in the inscription is also 
 opOai It is used in the same sense by Thucydides (v. 42), Avhere he says that 
 the Athenians thought that they were wronged by the destruction of Panac- 
 tum, 6 eSei 6p6ov napadovpat, and in chap. 46, UdvciKTOV re opOov atrohihovai Koi 
 'A/i0i7roXtv. The words inclosed between brackets in the last two lines are 
 restored upon conjecture, but probably are not far from the sense of the 
 original. In the place of the ninth letter from the end, there appear, however, 
 to be some traces of a N. 
 
 For aTTobihopevov in 1. 6, IMr. Dobree conjectured {nroTidepevov: see his 
 Miscellaneous Notes on Inscriptions, p. 13. 
 
 Concerning the word dnoriprfpa in 1. 4, see above, p. 143, note 682.
 
 470 
 
 BOOK IV. 
 
 OF THE EXTRAORDINARY REVENUES OF THE ATHENIAN 
 
 STATE. 
 
 Chapter I. 
 
 Subject of the Fourth Book stated. General nature of the 
 Property Tax in Attica, 
 
 The extraordinary revenues of the Athenian state, which stand 
 next for consideration, were either provided for as occasion 
 required, according to some established law or custom, or they 
 were raised by arbitrary measures, which, though repugnant to 
 the spirit of the constitution, the state was induced to have 
 recourse to in order to relieve itseK in pecuniary distresses. 
 
 With regard to the first of these modes, the imposts were of 
 two kinds, the one a fixed and direct tax, the other the litur- 
 gies. An acquaintance with both these methods of taxation 
 presupposes an investigation into the national wealth and 
 valuation of Attica, without which every inquiry of the sort 
 must be considered imperfect, obscure, and barren; yet the 
 writers on the liturgies up to this time have hardly bestowed a 
 thought upon the subject. Such an investigation is, indeed, 
 entangled with no small difficulties, so scanty, incomplete, and 
 indeterminate are the data which have come down to us. 
 
 This examination will be most suitably combined with that 
 of the property tax (etV<^opa), ^^^th which the determination of 
 the national wealth is closely connected. For it seems to have 
 been thought that the great demands which were occasioned by 
 war could not be satisfied in any better manner than by taxes 
 upon property; from which very circumstance it may be con- 
 cluded that these imposts did not exist in very early times. 
 Before the Peloponnesian war the Athenians had no occasion 
 to raise frequent and considerable taxes on property; the
 
 CH. I.] 
 
 SUBJECT OF THE FOURTH BOOK. 
 
 471 
 
 citizens served for a long time without pay, the ships were 
 equipped by the trierarchs, the sieges produced but httle 
 expense, as the art of conducting them was still in its infancy; 
 in later times, when pay was introduced, and wars had become 
 more costly, the expenses were defrayed out of the tributes. 
 It may, therefore, be reasonably doubted whether, before the 
 period alluded to, any direct tax whatever had been imposed at 
 Athens. If any had been levied, it must have been under the 
 name of a duty connected with the valuation {reXo^) ; a point, 
 indeed, upon which we are almost wholly uninformed, although 
 it appears to have been sometimes resorted to, since every 
 institution necessary for it was in existence, and the inquiry as 
 to the services due according to the valuation was already in use. 
 Of this, however, elsewhere. In the mean time, it is certain 
 that the first extraordinary property tax [eiG^opa) was occa- 
 sioned by the siege of Mytilene in Olyrap. 88, 1 (b. c. 428), 
 when, the public treasure being exhausted, 200 talents were 
 thus raised. This Thucydides' expressly testifies; and it is to 
 be observed, that he does not mean merely the first property 
 tax in the Peloponnesian war, but the first absolutely; for such 
 is the correctness of his style, that he would have more dis- 
 
 ' iii, 19j wliicli passage should evi- 
 dently be thus written : UpoaBeofievoi 
 Se oi ^ABrjvaioi XPVH-^'''^^ ^^ "^h^ ttoXi- 
 opKiav Koi avTol ecreveyKavres Tore 
 npwTov eacpopav diaKocria raXavra, 
 e^eTrep-yj/av Koi iirl tovs ^vppa.-)(ovs 
 upyvpoXoyovs vavs deKa, &c. Comp. 
 Poppo Obser. p. 162. [The following 
 remarks upon this passage are made 
 by Tittmann, in his Darstellung der 
 Griechischen Staatsverfas&ungen, p. 41, 
 note 31. "That the extraordinary 
 property tax was not introduced at 
 Athens until the Peloponnesian vfox, 
 cannot, as it appeal's to me, be proved 
 from Thucyd iii. 19, the only meaning 
 which this passage can have is, that 
 the amount before collected had never 
 been so great as 200 talents. We are 
 told that the naucraii collected the 
 
 property taxes (Pollux viii. 108, Hesy- 
 cliius in V. vavKXapos, Ammonius in v. 
 vavKpapoi, Thomas Magister in v. 
 vavKK-qpoL, and Bockh himself remarks 
 it in book iv. chap. 6) ; but the appel- 
 lation Naucrari in this sense did not 
 exist after the time of C'leisthenes 
 (Schol. Aristoph. Nub. 37, Harpocra- 
 tion in v. dr}p.apxos, Pliotius in v. 
 vavKpapia 2, all from Aristotle), and 
 tlierefore we are compelled to suppose 
 that property taxes had existed at 
 Athens before the time of Cleisthenes. 
 And it appears also from Thucyd. i. 
 141, that the extraordinary property 
 taxes levied in war were throughout 
 Greece general before the Polopon- 
 nesian war, particularly in S])arta, 
 and probably in Athens as well.'" — 
 Transl, I
 
 472 SUBJECT OF THE FOURTH BOOK. [bK. IV. 
 
 tinctly signified the former meaning, had he intended to convey 
 it. Thus the property tax is also, by its later origin, distin- 
 guished from the liturgies. In subsequent times, however, 
 these taxes appear to have recurred in frequent succession, for 
 even in Olymp. 88, 4 (b.c. 425), Aristophanes'^ speaks of their 
 imposition as a common event ; but for any other object than 
 war, a property tax was scarcely ever levied at Athens, unless 
 it happened that the funds of the administration had been 
 already applied to the uses of war, and it was necessary that 
 they should be replaced by a property tax ; or that money was 
 required to pay off loans, as was the case after the government 
 of the thirty tyrants ; although in other states property taxes 
 were sometimes imposed in time of peace to provide even for 
 the payment of salaries ^ For this reason the generals were 
 not only entrusted with the management and collection of these 
 taxes, under the regulation of a decree of the people, but they 
 presided over the court of justice, in which the disputes con- 
 nected with this subject were decided"; as, for example, when 
 any person was too highly rated, which in early times, either 
 from hatred or revenge, not unfrequently occurred \ 
 
 It is to be observ'ed, that no citizen could be exempted 
 from the property tax, although this privilege was once granted 
 to some resident aliens, who had probably obtained an immu- 
 nity as members of a foreign state before the period of their 
 settlement in Attica^. According to Demosthenes this was 
 neither permitted by recent nor ancient laws, not even for the 
 descendants of Harmodius and Aristogiton^ The exemption 
 supposed to have existed in favour of the merchants cannot 
 be looked upon as at all established % orphans were indeed 
 exempted from the liturgies, but not from the property taxes, 
 as Heraldus has remarked^; for Demosthenes paid them when 
 an orphan, and if it had been done voluntarily, he would not 
 
 Eq. 922. I 7 Demosth. c. Lept. §.15 (p. 4G2, 
 Aristot. Polit. vi. 5. 15), §. 22 (p. 4G5, 1). 
 
 Wolf Proleg. in Lept. p. xciv. ^ See book i. ch. 15. 
 
 Aristox)li. ut sup. ^ Anim. vi. 1, 7. 
 
 See below chap. 10.
 
 CH. I.] SUBJECT OF THE FOURTH BOOK. 473 
 
 have failed to dwell upon such a circumstance, where he boasts 
 of having been the leader of a symmoria during his minority^". 
 Even the trierarchs were obliged to pay this impost'^; and the 
 only payment from which they could legally be exempted was 
 the advance of the property tax^\ Other opulent persons, if 
 they had not to serve the trierarchy, were a /o?'^ion hable to 
 the property tax ; so that all other members of the community, 
 who were subject to the performance of liturgies, were bound to 
 pay it, even if they could not be forced to serve the trierarchy^': 
 it is, in fact, evident from the nature of the case, that all persons 
 who were not completely destitute were subject to this tax, 
 even if they were incapable of performing liturgies. 
 
 Chapter II. 
 
 The Sources of Wealth in Attica, and the Measures adopted by 
 the State for increasing it. 
 
 How much the state took from the property of individuals, 
 what sum could be supplied, if a fixed portion of it was 
 required, and according to what principles the taxation was 
 assessed, cannot be clearly understood without a knowledge of 
 the national wealth. 
 
 Since I shall endeavour to explain this question, it will not 
 be foreign to purpose, in the first instance, to inquire what 
 were the sources of wealth which Attica actually possessed, 
 and how far that care for the increase of the national wealth, 
 which has (no matter whether successfully or not) been 
 attempted by modern governments, was an object much con- 
 sidered by the administration of Athens. 
 
 Not to dwell on this subject longer than is necessary, I 
 
 ^° C.Mid.p. oG5. Another example SoopoS. p. 698 sqq. pro Aristopli. bonis 
 of a property tax paid for wards occiu's p. 633. Demostli. c. Lept. § 24 (p. 
 
 in Isseus ap. Dionys. Is. p. 108, 5, ac- 
 cording to the correct explanation of 
 Reiske, Or. Grsec. vol. vii. p. 331. 
 '^ Xenoph. (Econ. 2, 6. Lys. uttoX. 
 
 465, 25). 
 
 '* See book iii. ch. 21. 
 ^3 Demosth. c. Lept. ibid.
 
 474 THE SOURCES OF WEALTH. [bK. IV. 
 
 shall content myself with remarking, that in a democracy the 
 importance of the welfare and prosperity of the people must 
 have been more evident than under any other form of govern- 
 ment. Poverty would either produce troubles and violent 
 commotions, or the burthen of maintaining the poor would 
 press on the community at large. If the distress should be 
 prolonged, the possibility of enforcing the public liturgies 
 would be rendered doubtful. It is thus that the wealth of the 
 citizens produced far more immediate advantage to the state 
 than with any other constitution w^hatever. ^^The liturgies 
 voluntarily performed by individuals from their own property, 
 must be considered," says a client of Lysias'"*, "as the surest 
 revenues of the state. If, therefore, you counsel well, you will 
 take no less care of our property than of your own ; since you 
 well know that you will be able to make use of all our resources, 
 as you have done before. And I should conceive that you are 
 all well aware that I am a better manager of my own affairs 
 than those who administer the property of the state : if you 
 make me poor, you will, at the same time, injure yourselves, 
 and others will squander away my money, as has been so often 
 the case before.^' But although the prosperity of the common- 
 wealth depends upon the welfare of individuals, yet the remark 
 that every one is the best manager of his own property seems 
 to have been e^ddent to the Athenians, and, with the exception 
 of Sparta, to the other states of ancient Greece : they thought 
 that every one could best take care of himself, and that artificial 
 assistance was unnecessary. 
 
 Again, in the best times of the Athenian state, nothing 
 existed which could have impeded the public welfare ; except 
 that the liturgies, if they were unequally divided, were attended 
 with pernicious consequences. The property taxes were only 
 imposed in times of war, and the duties of customs and excise 
 were inconsiderable. Attica derived her prosperity from 
 agriculture and the breeding of cattle, from manufactures and 
 commerce. For the encouragement of trade everything was 
 done which was considered advantageous. Retail-trade or 
 
 ^^ Lys. dnoX. dwpob. p. 'JOA.
 
 CH. II.] 
 
 THE SOURCES OF WEALTH. 
 
 475 
 
 shop-keeping was not, indeed, an honourable employment, but 
 according to law it could not bring disgrace upon any one' \ 
 Agriculture stood high in the public estimation, and particular 
 branches of it were protected by law, such, for example, as the 
 cultivation of olives. Mining flourished as much as circum- 
 stances would permit : nor was the breeding of cattle discou- 
 raged by any taxes, as in countries under a despotic government. 
 No restraint was ever placed upon industry at Athens'^, although 
 manual labour was considered unworthy of a citizen. The law 
 proposed by Diophantus, as it was never actually passed, must 
 not be quoted as an example to the contrary; this person 
 wished to degrade the manual labourers to the condition of 
 public slaves {Brj/jioatoi); that is, to deprive them of the rights 
 of citizenship, and to reduce them to a condition similar to that 
 of the Cretan Clarotee, the Penestse, or the Helots ; a project 
 altogether at variance ^4th the spirit of the age, and emanating 
 from the violence of aristocratical oppression, by the operation 
 of which Athens would have been again degraded to that level 
 above which she had raised herself ever since the time of Solon. 
 This attempt, however, was just as impracticable as if it had 
 been wished again to introduce bondage in a state where it had 
 been long abolished, or to make the citizens in the republics 
 the slaves of the nobility*. 
 
 Many demagogues particularly encouraged manufactures and 
 industry, as has been noticed in difi^erent places; and in few 
 states were they so flourishing as in Athens. According to very 
 ancient laws, vagrants who followed no occupation v/ere not 
 tolerated; every person was obliged to signify by what means he 
 supported himself''^. Against the unemployed poor the action 
 for idleness [Blkt] apyla^) could be instituted'^: the law did not 
 even allow unemployed slaves {apyol olKerat) to be kept'^ 
 Parents were bound to cause their children to be taught some 
 profession, or they had no claim to be maintained by them in 
 
 '5 Petit Leg. Att. v. 6, 5. 
 '^ Comp. Ijook i. eh. 9. 
 * Concerning the proposal of Dio- 
 phantus, see b. i. note 178. — Traksl. 
 
 ^' Herod, ii. 177, Diod. i. 77. 
 '8 Comp. Petit v. G, 1. 
 '9 Petit ii. 6. 12.
 
 476 PROPERTY OF CITIZENS^ AND [bK. IV. 
 
 old age^'. Unfortunately indeed those laws^ as is usually the 
 case, fell into disuse, as the powers of the state were more fully 
 developed, and by means of wars and the system of judica- 
 ture, many hands were withdrawn from labour; the wages in 
 the assembly, in the courts of justice, and in the army and navy, 
 were looked to as professional rewards, and they appeared the 
 less disadvantageous to the state, as the expenses were in great 
 part defrayed out of the revenues of subject communities. 
 
 Chapter III. 
 
 Imtances of the Property of Athenian Citizens, and of the Dis- 
 tribution of the National Wealth among the different classes 
 of the People. 
 
 In order to give an idea of the national wealth of Attica, it is 
 first of all necessary to adduce examples of the property of 
 individuals (though from their nature they cannot be perfectly 
 vouched for), so that by a comparison of them it may be made 
 evident what was a small, and what a moderate or a large pro- 
 perty, particularly with regard to the interval of time between 
 Pericles and Alexander. Previously to this period, property 
 when valued in silver, was naturally of far less amount. 
 
 The Alcmseonidse were always a noble and wealthy family at 
 Athens; but their fortunes were chiefly raised in the age of 
 Solon by Alcmeeon the son of Megacles, Croesus having made 
 him a present of twice as much gold as he could carry* ^ In 
 this manner he might have received about 5 talents of gold, 
 which at the most amounted to 75 talents of silver; his former 
 property was probably not a third or fourth part of this sum : 
 and although he may at that time have far exceeded all his 
 fellow-citizens in wealth, yet at a later period this would no 
 longer have been the case. On the other hand, we meet in the 
 same age with many instances of inconsiderable properties; how 
 
 ^ Petit, ii. 4, 13, IG. [Dionysius i (os abiKovvrai to kolvov €^r]fiiovv- 
 Ant. Rom. XX. 2. 'Ad7]va7oi fxev 86^t]s Traxsl.] 
 
 eTvxov, OTL Tovs paQvixovs Kill dpyovs '. ='' Herod, vi. 125, and the commenta- 
 Kal fjLTjdtv eniTTibevovTas T(av xPW-l^^^ *'0^'S.
 
 CH. III.] DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 477 
 
 many persons were there who had not so much as a talent, or 
 even less than 10 minas; of which it is needless to quote any 
 examples, as poverty was generally prevalent. The possessor 
 of a talent was able indeed to live upon it, so that he was not 
 exactly classed with the indigent; but yet a property of this 
 amount w^as always inconsiderable. Families of 1 or 2 talents 
 [oIkol raXavrtaloL, SirdXavroi), which were numerous, did not 
 therefore serve any liturgies". Families possessing 3, 4, and 5 
 talents are frequently mentioned; thus ^schines the orator 
 inherited an estate of 5 talents, which he farther increased by 
 his own gains; thus, for example, he added to it, according 
 to Demosthenes, 2 talents, which the managers of the sym- 
 moriee had given him^^ Isseus^^ furnishes an instance of an 
 estate of nearly 4 talents, one of whose clients states that he 
 had land in CEnoe worth 50 minas, together with the estate of 
 Hagnias amounting to 2 talents 40 minas, to which 10 minas 
 must be added for some item that has fallen out of the MSS., 
 making altogether 3 talents 40 minas. Stratocles and his 
 brother, according to the account of Iseeus^^, received from 
 their father a fortune just sufficient for their maintenance, from 
 which however they were not able to perform any liturgies; 
 Stratocles by the adoption of his daughter obtained a property 
 of more than 2^ talents, and gained by being in possession of 
 this sum for nine years 5^ talents, partly in money, raw pro- 
 ducts, and cattle, partly in lands and agricultural implements, 
 which, together with the property of his daughter, amounted to 
 8 talents. The property of Critobulus is estimated by Xeno- 
 
 *^ Bookiii. ch. 21. 
 ^3 Demosth. de Corona, p. 329, 15. 
 De Hagn. Hered. p. 294. In 
 
 as this : ;(copioj/ ev Olvorj TrevraKicrxi' 
 Xlcov, oIkiu xi-^i-^^v. The npos de tov- 
 Tois which follows shows that two sepa- 
 
 order to understand this passage I I rate suras preceded. As to the rest 
 
 must make the following remarks. 
 
 The speaker's property is stated to be 
 
 about 110 minas less than the property 
 
 of Stratocles. Now the property of 
 
 Stratocles amounted to 330 minas; 
 
 consequently the property of the for- ; 
 
 mer person must have been 220. | Minerva natus sum. 
 
 Sometiing must therefore have fallen \ '^^ Ibid. p. 292 sqq. 
 
 out, and be restored in some such way i 
 
 the calculation is quite clear, and 
 though Reiske cannot see^^his way 
 through it, we excuse him for the sake 
 of his frank confession (p. 295) : 
 Verum, fatebor enim, ad calculandum et 
 omnes omnino artes mathematicas invita
 
 478 PROPERTY OF CITIZENS, AND [bK IV. 
 
 phon'° at 500 niinas (8^ talents) and over: he was considered a 
 rich man. Tiinocrates was possessed of more than 10 talents''^; 
 Dicaeogenes had an annual income of 80 minas^% which impHes 
 a property of about 11 talents, and this was looked upon as 
 something considerable. Diodotus, a merchant in moderate 
 circumstances, was possessed, according to the statement of 
 Lysias*% of 5 talents of silver, which he paid down to the guar- 
 dian appointed for his children; he had 7f talents vested in 
 bottomry, and 1000 drachmas in the Chersonese, and besides 
 bequeathed to his wife 2000 drachmas and 30 Cyzicenic staters; 
 to this must be added the furniture of his house, and perhaps 
 an estate in the Chersonese, from which his family received 
 supplies of corn every year, amounting altogether to 14 talents. 
 Demosthenes' father left at his death 14 talents, his mother had 
 a dowry of 50 minas, so that the property of the son was esti- 
 mated in the registers of the valuation at 15 talents^". Under 
 it the following articles were comprised; two workshops with 
 thirty sword-cutlers and twenty chair-makers, a talent lent out 
 at 12 per cent., together valued at 4 talents 50 minas, the yearly 
 profit of which was 50 minas; moreover, about 80 minas in 
 ivory, iron, and timber, 90 in varnish and brass, a house worth 
 30 minas, furniture, cups, gold, clothes, ornaments, belonging to 
 his mother, worth 100 minas, 80 minas in ready money, 70 
 minas lent out upon bottomry, and 106 minas lent out in other 
 ways, altogether about 14 talents: in this enumeration the 
 female slaves are not included^'. Pheenippus^^ had an estate on 
 the borders in Cytheron, of 40 square stadia at the lowest, the 
 yearly returns of which were more than 1000 medimni of barley 
 and 800 metretee of wine, from which in dear times, when 
 barley was at ]8 and wine at 12 drachmas, he received 27,600 
 
 ^c CRcon. 2, comp. book i.ch. 20. Chersonese instead of 1000. [The 
 
 -'' Demosth. c. Onetor. i. p. 8CG, former number has however been re- 
 
 oxtr. 
 
 '^ Isteus do Dicseog. Hered. p. 110. 
 
 ■■'^ In Diogit. p. 894 sqq. I cannot 
 see any sufficient reason why Canter 
 and Taylor (p. 902, Kciske) should 
 
 ceived by Bekkor from a MS., Or. Att. 
 i. p. 469.— Traxsl.] 
 
 3« Demosth. c. Aphob. pp. 814, 815. 
 
 3» P. 828, 2. 
 
 ^* See the speech against Phaenippus 
 
 'ish to read 2000 drachmas in tlie p. 1040, and there Reiske.
 
 CH. III.J DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 479 
 
 drachmas : if we take only the fourth part as the common price 
 (although the orator assumes the third part), he received from it 
 regularly an income of 7000 drachmas : besides this he sold 
 wood from it every year which produced 40 minas. He had 
 therefore an annual income of about 110 minas, whence his 
 estate, according to the usual interest of 1 2 per cent., cannot be 
 estimated at less than 15 talents. 
 
 The owner of this amount of property was considered as 
 a person of some opulence, as the rate of interest was high and 
 the prices of commodities low. At the same time many Athe- 
 nians were far wealthier. Onetor, according to Demosthenes'^, 
 was possessed of more than 30 talents; Ergocles is also said to 
 have embezzled the same sum^*. The property of Isocrates 
 cannot have been less, for he had at one time about 100 scho- 
 lars, and received from each 10 minas, from Timotheus a talent, 
 from Euagoras 20 talents^\ Conon left at his death about 40 
 talents, of which he bequeathed 5000 staters, about 100,000 
 drachmas to Minerva and the Delphian Apollo, 10,000 drachmas 
 to a relation, 3 talents to his brother, after which 17 talents 
 remained for his son Timotheus^^: perhaps however only the 
 ready money is intended, for the family appears to have pos- 
 sessed much landed property from early times^^ Stephanus 
 the son of ThaUus passed for a man worth more than 50 talents, 
 yet he only left behind him^^ 11 talents, probably because he 
 had squandered away much money in the course of an extra- 
 vagant life. In the same manner Ischomachus was considered 
 in his lifetime to have possessed more than 70 talents^% yet 
 after his death his two sons received only 2 talents a piece; but 
 flatterers and parasites had consumed his substance^*', so that it 
 cannot be wondered that he left at his death less than it was 
 thought that he possessed; it is only a matter of surprise that 
 Xenophon"*^ should quote this man, if the same person is really 
 meant, as an example of economy. The property of the cele- 
 
 ^■■^ C. Onetor. p. 867, 1. 
 
 '^* Lysias c. Philocr. p. 828. 
 
 ^•^ Lives of the Ten Orators. 
 
 ^* Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 030. 
 
 37 Plutarch. Solon. 15. 
 
 3^ Lysias ut sup. p. 648. 
 
 ^^ Lys. ut sup. p. C47. 
 
 '^^ Heraclid. ap. Athen. xii. p. 5.37, D. 
 
 ^' (Econ. 6 sqq.
 
 480 
 
 PROPERTY OF CITIZENS, AND 
 
 [bK. IV. 
 
 brated l)anker Pasion, a naturalized foreigner, was of equal 
 magnitude; he possessed about 20 talents in land, including a 
 shield manufactory, and slaves which produced a talent a year; 
 and in addition to this, 50 talents of money lent out at inter- 
 est, of which 1 1 talents were not his own"*'. His houses alone 
 yielded a rent of 30 minas a year; the banking-shop produced 
 an annual income of 100 minas. His son Apollodorus, who 
 inherited the half of his property, not only lived extravagantly, 
 but devoted a large part of his property to the public service"*^. 
 It appears also from the works of Demosthenes that he was 
 involved in many law-suits; which will account for his being 
 found to possess no more than 3 talents'** when he was called 
 upon to pay a large fine, although he is said to have received 
 more than 40 talents in twenty years. 
 
 Among the wealthy families I should first mention the house 
 of Nicias. Nicias the son of Niceratus, the unfortunate general, 
 was remarkable for his large possessions, from which he con- 
 tributed munificently both to the state and to the worship of 
 the gods"*^. This is the person whom Atheneeus calls the richest 
 of all the Greeks; his property was so considerable that, 
 according to Xenophon, he had 1000 slaves of his own in his 
 mines'^ That this is the individual alluded to by Xenophon 
 does not require any proof, for he is evidently speaking of a 
 person of the age of Socrates; his property was valued at 100 
 talents, consisting chiefly of moveables*^. His son Niceratus, 
 who is called nearly the most distinguished and the wealthiest 
 person in Athens*^, was killed at the time of the thirty tyrants, 
 who were tempted by his wealth to put him to death. He 
 
 42 Demosth. c. Phorin. pp. 945, 946. 
 The words 'Ev ovp to7s TrevTr^Kovra tu- 
 XdvTOLi,' occasion in this place a con- 
 siderable difficulty, which the com- 
 mentators have not thought proper to 
 touch upon. According to the sense 
 their meaning must be, that together 
 with his own 50 talents he had also 
 lent out 11 belonging to other people. 
 Heraldus (ii. 5, 13 sqq.) therefore pro- 
 poses to read avp ovv : perhaps how- 
 ever eV can be retained, in the sense of 
 
 among his own 50 talents, between 
 them, as it were intermixed with them. 
 
 *^ Demosth. ut sup. p. 956 sqq. 
 
 ^ Orat. c. Neaer. p. 1354, 16. 
 
 ^5 Thucyd. vii. 86. 
 
 *^ Athen. vi. p. 272 E, Xenophon 
 ^[emorab. ii. 5, 2, de Vectig. 4, 14, 
 Plutarch. Nic. 4, comp. book i. ch. 13. 
 
 ■*7 Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. 648. 
 
 4^ Diod. xiv. 5 ; comp. Xenoph. 
 Hell. ii. 3, 18, Lys. c. Poliuch. p. 602, 
 riutarch. Es. Carn. ii. 4.
 
 CH. III.] DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 
 
 481 
 
 affirmed that he neither left behind him gold nor silver; but 
 his son Nicias received 14 talents in land^ and other property*'. 
 I conjecture therefore that Niceratus had previously made some 
 secret transfer of his property, and I find a slight confirmation 
 of this supposition in the account given by Isocrates'" of a 
 Nicias, who in the time of the thirty tyrants mortgaged his 
 lands, sent his slaves out of the country, and gave his money 
 and furniture in trust to a friend. This was probably the son 
 of the Nicias who was executed, and it is possible that his 
 father may have transferred the property to him previously to 
 his voyage from Athens; the Nicias of Pergase, who squandered 
 away his substance with flatterers^^, is probably the same 
 person; and Niceratus of Acherdus, notwithstanding the differ- 
 ence of the demus, appears to be his son, whom Demos- 
 thenes^^ calls a son of Nicias, beloved, childish, and effeminate, 
 who was still alive in Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353), and since he 
 was able to perform the trierarchy, must have still retained a 
 considerable property; with him this celebrated family became 
 extinct. 
 
 Still more distinguished both in rank and in wealth was the 
 
 ■^^ Lys. pro Aristopli. bonis ut sup. 
 The date of this oration is Olymp. 98, 
 wliich must be observed in order to 
 prevent confusion between the diiFer- 
 ent individuals of this family. 
 
 ^' C. Euthyn. 3. 
 
 5' Athen. xii. p. 537 D, ^lian V. II, 
 iv. 23. 
 
 " C. Mid. p. 567, 24, cf. p. 568, 24. 
 The same person is probably meant in 
 Demosth. de Fals. Leg. p. 534, 15, c. 
 Conon. p. 1266, 26. In this account 
 of the family of Nicias, having paid no 
 regard to the errors of modern scho- 
 lars, I will now touch upon them 
 slightly. The confusion which St. 
 Croix (M^m. de I'Acad. des Inscrip- 
 tions, t. xlviii. pp. 165, 172) has made, 
 is the most singular, as he refers the 
 passages of Xenophon and Atl>en8eus 
 concerning Nicias the general, who 
 was executed in Sicily, to his grandson 
 
 Nicias, and asserts of the other that he 
 died childless, referring to Demosthenes 
 against Meidias, where his great grand- 
 son Niceratus is said to have died with- 
 out children. Markland (ad Lys. pro 
 Aristoph. bonis) supposes that the 
 childless Niceratus was the Niceratus 
 who was executed in Olpnp. 04, 1, and 
 by that means involves himself in in- 
 extricable difficulties, from which he 
 wishes to relieve himself by an absurd 
 emendation : the truth however is that 
 the one vras the grandfather of the 
 other. The elder died in Olymp. 94, 
 1, the younger was living at the time 
 of the suit against Meidias. That the 
 former had a son may be also seen 
 from Lys. c. PoUuch. p. 604. Spalding 
 also (ad Mid.) and Reiske (Ind. His- 
 tor. ad Demosth.) have confounded 
 these two persons.
 
 482 
 
 PROPERTY GF CITIZENS, AND 
 
 Fbk. 
 
 family of Hipponicus and Callias, ^yhich derived its origin from 
 Triptolemus, and had the hereditary dignity of torch-bearer 
 {BaBov'x^os') in the Eleusinian mysteries". The first of this 
 family whom we hear of was the Hipponicus, who is said to 
 have bought much land with borrowed money a short time 
 before the changes introduced by Solon in the 46th Olympiad 
 (B.C. 594y\ It should be observed, however, that as a charge 
 of having obtained his wealth unjustly is implied in this state- 
 ment, it may have originated in the envy of his countrymen. 
 Pheenippus, the father of the first CalUas^ was probably his 
 brother; this Callias had large possessions, and he bought the 
 property of Pisistratus as often as he was driven out", expended 
 much money in keeping horses, was conqueror in the Olympic 
 games, gave great dowries to his daughters, and permitted a]l 
 three the liberty of choosing among the Athenians whatever 
 husbands they wished. His son Hipponicus the second, sur- 
 named Ammon, is said to have been made still richer than his 
 father by the treasures of a Persian general which Diomnestus 
 of Eretria had acquired on the first irruption of the Persians 
 into Greece (Olymp. 72, 3, B.C. 490), and which upon the 
 second invasion he gave in custody to Hipponicus; and the 
 latter, as all the captive Eretrians were sent to x\sia, was unable 
 to return them^^; a story, which is deserving of credit, since 
 even the name of the Eretrian is mentioned. Callias the 
 second, the torch-bearer, called Laccoplutus from his great 
 riches, was the son of this Hipponicus; he was held to be the 
 richest of the Athenians^^, and his property was valued at 200 
 talents'^; he was appointed ambassador to the Persian court, 
 and subsequently paid a fine of 50 talents to the state^^ He 
 
 53 Xenoph. Hell. vi. 3, 2, Andoc. de 
 Myst. p. 57 sqq. and elsewhere in the 
 account of Callias the second. 
 
 ^* Plut. Solon. 15. 
 
 " Herod, vi. 121. 
 
 ^ Heraclid. Pont. ap. Athen. xii. p. 
 536 F. 
 
 57 Plut. Aristid. 25. 
 
 '^ Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis, p. (140 
 sqq. 
 
 s** See book iii. ch. 12. The author 
 mentions in the Addenda that "since 
 Callias the second, the torch-bearer 
 gained such fame by the conclusion of 
 the peace of Cimon, that the Athe- 
 nians are said to have erected at that 
 time an altar to Peace (Plutarcli. Ci- 
 mon. 1.3), one might be inclined to 
 question the reality of the fines to 
 which he is said to have been con-
 
 en. III.] DISTRIBLTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 483 
 
 is said to have obtained his cognomen from an occurrence 
 which took place at the battle of Marathon, at which there can 
 be no doubt that he was present: the story is, that a Persian 
 pointed out to him a treasure buried in the earth, that he killed 
 the communicator of the secret, and carried away the money; 
 it is however more probable that this faille arose from his cog- 
 nomen, and from the account handed down concerning his 
 father, especially as the story is differently narrated, and the 
 battle of Salamis substituted for that of Marathon^". His larire 
 possessions passed into the hands of his son Hipponicus the 
 third, whose wife afterwards married Pericles; in family and 
 riches this one too is ranked among the first of the Greeks'". 
 According to Xenophon he had 600 slaves in the mines, and he 
 is even said to have applied for and obtained permission from 
 the state to build a house upon the Acropolis, in which to 
 deposit his treasures, as they were not sufficient^ secure at his 
 own residence; a circumstance which appears afterwards to 
 have vexed him when he was reminded of it by his friends^^. 
 His daughter, who married Alcibiades, received a dowry of 10 
 talents, which was the first instance of so large a sum having 
 been given by a Grecian; 10 others were to be added w^hen 
 she had a son'^^ Hipponicus was killed in the battle of Delium 
 (Olymp. 89, B.C. 424), where he was general: and Callias the 
 third, the torch-bearer, succeeded him, who must have inherited 
 his father^s property when a youth; he w^as celebrated for his 
 riches and liberality. Sophists, flatterers, and courtesans, 
 helped to consume his substance. When he filled the office 
 of general (Olymp. 96, 4, B.C. 393), he probably spent his own 
 
 demned. Pausanias (1, 8, 3) on the j not erected till later times, and for 
 
 other hand, influenced by the latter ' that reason cannot afford any decisive 
 
 circumstance, appears even to question | testimony in his favour." 
 
 the merits of Callias as merely relying j ^^ The passages are Plut. Aristld. 5, 
 
 upon popular report; the Athenians ' Schol.Aristoph. Nub. Go, Hesych.Suid. 
 
 indeed recognised them by the erec- and Photius in v. XukkottXovtos. 
 
 tion of a metal statue to his memory, | ^^ Andoc. de ]\r,\st. p. 64, Isocr. 
 
 which, however, as well as the statues nepl tov C^vy. 13, Plut. Alcib. 8. 
 
 of Lycurgus, of Demostlienes, and of , ^^ Heraclid. ut sup. 
 
 the goddess of Peace, together with | ^3 pj^^t. Alcib. ut sup. Andoc. c. 
 
 which it stood, were unquestionably Alcib. p. 1 17- 
 
 2 I 2
 
 484 PROPERTY OF ClTIZEXS, AND [liK. IV. 
 
 private fortune instead of increasing it: the duties of the 
 Spartan proxenia may also have been performed by him in an 
 expensive manner. About the 98th Olympiad (b.c. 388) his 
 property did not amount to 2 talents; and at an advanced age, 
 after having gone as ambassador to Sparta so late as in Olymp. 
 102, 2 (b.c. 371)5 he died in indigence^*. His son, Hipponicus 
 the fourth, cannot therefore have inherited much from his 
 father. Whether Callias, the son of Calliades, who gave Zeno 
 100 minas for instructing him®^, and, as is evident from this fact, 
 was a man of considerable wealth, belonged to this family, 
 cannot be determined; but the rich Callias of inferior descent, 
 who obtained his property by mining, and who paid for Cimon 
 the great fine imposed on Miltiades®% was unconnected with 
 this house. 
 
 The property of Alcibiades, who was doubly related to the 
 noble Callias, was very considerable. His family estate only 
 indeed amounted to 300 plethra of land, although Cleinias his 
 ancestor, doubtless his great-grandfather, is mentioned among 
 those who made a dishonest use of the seisachtheia of Solon, 
 for the purpose of increasing their property®^; and the orna- 
 ments of his mother Deinomache are estimated by Socrates, as 
 mentioned in Plato (or whoever was the author of the first Al- 
 cibiades), at only 50 minas. There cannot however be any 
 doubt that he had much other property, for his father Cleinias 
 
 ^* Concerning tlie reduced circum- | xiv. 16, Larcher ad Herod, vi. 121, 
 stances of this Callias, see Heraclid. ut ! Klister ad Aristoph. Av. 284, and the 
 
 Slip. Lysias ut sup. (in Olymp. 96) 
 /Elian. Var. Hist. iv. 16, 23 ; and com- 
 pare Perizonius upon the latter passage. 
 
 writers quoted by Fischer ad Plat. 
 Apol. 4. I have only here wished to 
 adduce what relates to their wealth, 
 
 Concerning him as general, ambassa- j and to the distinction between tlie 
 
 dor, daduchus, and Spartan proxenus, \ different individuals. 
 
 see Xenoph. Hell. iv. 5, 13, v. 4, 22, j "^ Plat. Alcib. i. p. 119 A, and there 
 
 vi. 3, 2 sqq. and in order to obtain the j Buttmann. 
 
 date of the event mentioned in the ^^ Pint. Cim. 4, Nepos Cini. I. 
 
 last passage, Diod. xv. 51, and the com- j ^'^ Plat. Alcib. i. p. 123 C, Plut. Sol. 
 
 mentators. The jest of Iphicrates in i 15. With regard to the double rela- 
 
 Aristot. Rhet. iii. 2, refers to the po- j tionship, Alcibiades' mother was of 
 
 verty of this vain and noble torch- the family of Hipponicus (Dem. adv. 
 
 bearer. He is well known from Plato. Mid. p. 561, 20; conip. Spalding, p. 74 
 
 Many have written upon this family, sqq.), and he himself married the sis- 
 
 particularly Perizon. ad yElian. V. H. ter of Callias.
 
 CH. III.] DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH, 
 
 485 
 
 had a trireme of his own in the Persian war, which he manned 
 at his private cost: and his gains could not have been trifling 
 during the four or five years that he was general, as the different 
 states willingly gave him twice as much as they gave to others: 
 his property was estimated at more than 100 talents, and if we 
 find that he left behind him less than he had received from his 
 guardians''^, this fact can only be explained by his profligacy and 
 extravagance, and the extraordinary reverses of his life. 
 
 Upon the whole, the office of general and places connected 
 with the administration of public money enriched the persons 
 who filled them. Themistocles was not possessed of 3 talents 
 before he entered upon the management of public affairs, and he 
 had no scruples about taking money w^hen any favourable occa- 
 sion offered. Thus he received 30 talents from the Euboeans 
 for an object of great utility, of which he embezzled 25, having 
 attained his purpose wdth only 5'% when he fled to Asia, he 
 saved part of his property by the assistance of some friends, 
 and yet what accrued to the state, according to Theopompus, 
 amounted to 100 talents, according to others to still more, and 
 according to Theophrastus to SO'**. Cleon the leather-seller 
 w^as so deeply involved in debt, that nothing that he had was 
 unmortgaged, before he became a demagogue; his well-known 
 rapacity gained him 50, or, according to another reading, 100 
 talents^'. The account is unquestionably exaggerated which 
 Dinarchus"* gives of Demosthenes having by Persian and other 
 bribes gradually obtained 150 talents, although he was not pos- 
 sessed of any landed property, and was not even able to pay 
 the fine, when judgment was passed against him in the case of 
 Harpalus. Of others who lived in the same age the last I shall 
 mention is Diphilus, whose confiscated property produced 160 
 talents^'. Common report ascribed to Epicrates, as Lycurgus 
 mentioned, a property of 600 talents^*. 
 
 ^^ Lys de Aristoph. bonis, p. 654. 
 °^ Herod, viii. 4, 5. 
 "^^ Plut. Themist. 25, M\\&n. Var. 
 Hist. X. 17." 
 
 "'^ ^lian.ut sup. and there Perizon. 
 "''^ Adv. Dcniosth. pp. 50, 51. 
 
 7^ Lives of the Ten Orators in the Life 
 of Lycurgus. Conip. above, book i. 
 cli. 7, and my Dissertation upon the 
 Silver-mines of Laurium. 
 
 ''* Ilarpocrat. and Suidas in v. 'Etti- 
 
 KpUTr]S.
 
 486 
 
 PROPERTY OF CITIZENS. AND 
 
 [bk. IV 
 
 Altliongh these data are not sufficient to express the national 
 wealth in a determinate number, yet they justify us generally 
 in asserting that it was not inconsiderable, as compared with 
 the actual circumstances of Greece. Demosthenes'^, in refe- 
 rence to this very point, states that the resources of Athens 
 were nearly equal to those of all the other states. It ap- 
 pears that in the better times property was divided into 
 nearly equal portions; that is to say, most persons had only as 
 much as they used: no one was so poor that he disgraced the 
 state by begging'^: the rich however shared their property with 
 the poor in order to obtain popularity, as was the case with 
 Cimon; and when we are told that the people was poor 
 [irevv^s]", this statement refers to the more recent times; nor, 
 according to the Grecian idiom, does it mean that the majority 
 of the nation were wholly destitute of property. The land also 
 appears to have been much divided; even wealthy citizens, 
 such as Alcibiades or Aristophanes^^ did not possess more 
 than 30 plethra, or thereabouts. In the age of Demosthenes 
 we meet for the first time with complaints that individuals got 
 possession of too many, or very extensive estates^^; of which 
 Phsenippus and Pasion the banker are instances. At the return 
 of the people after the overthrow of the thirty tyrants, there 
 were not more than 5000 citizens who did not possess any 
 land^^, and some of these probably had other property. 
 
 In later times, although it appears that many of the citizens 
 fell into great poverty, and that a few only rose to opulence, 
 the wealth of individuals never reached such a height as in the 
 Macedonian kingdoms, and in the Roman state; whence 
 Cicero" declares that 50 talents was a great sum of money, 
 particularly at Athens in the age of Alexander. When Anti- 
 pater in Olymp. 114, 2 (b.c. 323) deprived all Athenians of the 
 full rights of citizenship who did not possess 2000 drachmas. 
 
 "'^ De Synnnor. p. 105, 2, cf. adv. 
 Aiulrot. p. 617, 12, Thucyd. i. 80, ii. 
 40. 
 
 ^^ Isocrat. Areopag. 38. 
 
 '" Xenoph. de Vectig. and do Rep. 
 Ath. 
 
 '8 Mentioned by Lysias. See book 
 i.cli. 11. 
 
 '" Book i. cli. 12. 
 
 «" Dionys. Hal. Lvs. p. 92, 44, ed. 
 Sylb. 
 
 ''^ Tusc. V. 32.
 
 CH. III.] DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 48/ 
 
 12,000 persons''' are said to have been thus excluded; conse- 
 quently not more than about 9000 can have been possessed of 
 that sum; in the time of Cassander 10 minas were sufficient 
 qualification for the full rights of a citizen^': these rates are so 
 low, that it might seem preferable not to consider them as esti- 
 mates of the whole property, but as fixed parts of it with refer- 
 ence to the imposition of taxes, which was the nature of the 
 valuations of Solon and Nausinicus; but this again is impossible, 
 as in that case too large an amount of property would have 
 been requisite to entitle the possessor to the rights of citizen- 
 ship; we must therefore consider those rates as real valuations 
 of property, and suppose that Athens had greatly declined in 
 wealth. For the earlier times it would be important to know 
 how much property qualified a citizen for admission among the 
 5000 hoplitee during the government of the Four Hundred; but 
 we only know in general that bodily strength and opulence were 
 requisite^^ 
 
 Chapter IV. 
 
 Approximate Determination of the National Wealth of Attica. 
 
 Concerning the total amount of the national wealth of Attica, 
 Polybius^^ gives an apparently most satisfactory statement. 
 Phylarchus had related that Cleomenes before the battle of Sel- 
 lasia collected 6000 talents from the plunder of Megalopolis: 
 this sum, which, according to Polybius, would have enabled the 
 king of Sparta to exceed even Ptolemy in civil and military 
 expenses, our historian will not allow to be correct ; at that 
 period, he maintains, when the Peloponnese was completely 
 exhausted, as much unquestionably could not have been levied 
 out of it, as in his own, when the country was in a flourishing 
 condition, and yet that at the actual time they could not, 
 excluding the inhabitants, and counting in all kinds of furniture 
 and implements, make up 6000 talents : " For what historian,'' 
 
 «^ Book i. ch. 7. I ^* Thv.cycl viii. Go, conf. 97. 
 
 «3 Diod. xviii. 74. 1 "' »• ^'-^ ^"^'"f- ^■*-
 
 4B8 ArnioxiMATE determination of [bk. IV. 
 
 he proceeds to say, " has not related of the Atlienians, that, at 
 the time when in conjunction with Thebes they entered upon 
 the war against the Lacedaemonians, they sent out 10,000 
 soldiers, and manned 100 triremes; that having then deter- 
 mined to pay the war taxes from property (aTro rr/s ovalas), 
 they valued the whole country of Attica, and the houses, and all 
 other property as well ; and nevertheless the whole valuation of 
 the property (to ovfJLirav ri/jbrjfjLa rf;? a^tas) wanted 250 of 6000 
 talents.^^ 
 
 How Ste. Croix^^ could imagine that Olymp. 103, 2 (b.c. 
 367) is here meant, I am at a loss to conceive ; for Polybius 
 points with sufficient clearness to the recent valuation made in 
 the archonship of Nausinicus, Olymp. 100, 3 (b.c. 378). In 
 this year the Athenians entered into an alliance with Thebes, 
 after the attempt of Sphodrias the Spartan upon the Piraeus 
 had miscarried, fortified this harbour, built new ships, and 
 assisted the Thebans to the utmost of their means : Demophon 
 was sent to their assistance with 5000 hoplitse and 500 
 cavalry; and, according to the statement of Diodorus (who, 
 pursuant to his usual custom, does not mention it till the 
 following year, and always exaggerates the numbers), they 
 agreed to send out 20,000 hoplitee, 500 cavalry, and 200 ships, 
 under the command of Timotheus^ Chabrias, and Callistratus : 
 the first consequence was the cession of the citadel Cadmea to 
 the Thebans'^ 
 
 A more exact statement upon our subject hardly appears 
 desirable. Polybius, the most accurate and judicious of writers, 
 furnishes us wdth a determination of the national wealth for a 
 particular period, and this according to the valuation, and con- 
 sequently upon the authority of public documents, which one 
 at least of his predecessors, who drew from the fountain-head. 
 
 ^^ Recherches sur la ropulation I transcribed from Harpocration is in- 
 d'Attique, Mem. de I'Acade'mie, t. 48, ' serted after the article 6 KarcoOcv vofios^ 
 p. 148. The same writer also relies | and appears to be imited with it. Kiis- 
 for the valuation of 6000 talents upon i ter had separated them. 
 Anaximenes; a gross error, the origin ^^ Xcnoph. Hell. v. 4, 34 sqq. Diod. 
 of which was that the article ort xv. 25 — 29. 
 f|oKicr;^iXta in f^uidas and Photiiis i
 
 CII. IV.] 
 
 THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 
 
 489 
 
 must have inspected. Nor can there exist any doubt that he 
 means every sort of property; for he calls it the valuation not 
 only of the lands of all Attica (xcopas) and the houses, but of 
 the other property also {rrjs XocTrrfs ova las). Moreover, it 
 nearly coincides with the statement of Demosthenes, who 
 reckons the valuation of the country {jlfjir^^a rrjs ')(^copa^) at 
 6000 talents^% as also Philochorus in the tenth book upon 
 Attica^^ Harpocration®" remarks, that the word valuation 
 {TLjjL7]fjLa) signifies capital; it is therefore impossible that the 
 annual revenue can be meant, even if we did not know that it 
 never amounted to so high a sum^'. 
 
 But however weighty the character of Poly bins, and how- 
 ever specious the agreement of the other authors, I yet hope to 
 bring forward such powerful arguments as will convict this 
 excellent historian of error, by showing, in the first place, that 
 5750 talents are, as may be collected from other circumstances, 
 too small a part of the national wealth of Attica to admit of our 
 supposing that it was only a valuation which was accidentally too 
 low, from the citizens having concealed much of their property? 
 and, secondly, I hope in the course of my investigation to point 
 out how Polybius fell into this error, and how the other pas- 
 sages, as well as the statement which he misunderstood, are to 
 be taken. 
 
 Property, according to the language of the Athenian law, 
 was divided into two classes, visible and invisible [ovala (pavepa 
 and d(f)av7](;). The latter of these classes included money, furni- 
 ture, slaves, &c.®^ The former included houses and lands; the 
 mines could not have been comprised under it, because no pro- 
 perty-tax or liturgy was paid from them, being held on herit- 
 able leases from the state. The corn-land alone amounted to 
 
 «^ De Spunior. p. 183, 5, p. 186, 18, \ 
 in Olymp. 106, 3 (b.c. 354). 
 
 ^^ Harpocrat. ut sup. In the manu- 
 script of Demosthenes, which Harpo- 
 cration used, it was incorrectly written 
 8000 talents. 
 
 ^^ In V. Tt/x77/xa. 
 
 °^ And yet Meursius (F. A. p. 51), 
 Petit (Leg. Att. iii. 2, 33), balniasius 
 
 (^lod. Usur. i. p. 28), and even Wink- 
 elmann, Avhom Heyne has corrected in 
 his Antiquarisclie Aufsatze, i. p. 205, 
 have tliought that the annual revenue 
 was liere meant. 
 
 ^^ Harpocrat. 'Acf)avr)s ovala kuI (f>a- 
 vepd : d(f)avr]S fX€U tj ev pcpTy/iacri Kal (tm- 
 ^aai Koi (TKfveo-i, (pauepci 8e r] eyyeios.
 
 490 APPROXIMATE DETERMI NATION OF [bK. IV. 
 
 more than 900,000 plethra; and as a plethron cannot at the 
 lowest be estimated at less than 50 drachmas'% the value of this 
 one item was more than 7500 talents. If from this sum we 
 deduct 500 talents for the property of the state, the taxable 
 corn-land alone exceeded by about 1250 talents the amount 
 given by Polybius; and as the land which grew corn did not 
 compose much more than the third part of the area of Attica, 
 we may safely add 2000 talents for the rest of the country, as 
 far as it was in the possession of private individuals or of tax- 
 able corporations, inclusive of the demi; so that the landed 
 property, taken at the lowest estimate, amounted to 9000 talents. 
 Moreover, Athens had 10,000 houses, besides the buildings in 
 the farms, in the villages and country towns^^ If each house 
 is reckoned on an average at 10 minas, which cannot according 
 to their ascertained value be an over-estimate, the sum we 
 obtain exceeds 1600 talents; to which 400 talents may be fairly 
 added for the buildings out of Athens; so that the immoveable 
 property alone amounts to nearly twice Polybius's statement. 
 To the value of the immoveable property may next be added 
 that of the slaves, who may be taken at 360,000; and if we 
 assume the value of each at only a mina", we obtain the sum 
 of 6000 talents. The value of the horses must also have been 
 considerable, as there was a body of cavalry which consisted of 
 1200 men, and an equal number of servants; and if we then 
 take into account the passion of the young men for horses, and 
 the expenses which many persons incurred for these animals, 
 that they might exhibit them at the sacred spectacles (as, for 
 example, Alcibiades, who sent seven chariots at one time to the 
 Olympic games^^), together with the number required for agri- 
 cultural purposes, our estimate rather errs on the side of defi- 
 ciency if we assume 3000 horses, and each upon an average at 
 5 minas^^, which gives the sum of 250 talents. To these we 
 will add only 1000 yokes of mules, at 6 minas, together making 
 100 talents: and will estimate all the cattle, sheep, goats, and 
 
 8^ See book i. cli. 15 and 11. 
 
 9^ Book i. ch. 12. 
 
 " Comp. book i. ch. 7 and i;}. 
 
 5« Time. vi. 15, IC. 
 "7 Book i. ch. 14.
 
 CH. IV.] THE NATIONAL WEALTH. 491 
 
 pigs, at no more than 250 talents. Again, the money accumu- 
 lated and lent out at interest could not have been inconsider- 
 able in amount, if a banker like Pasion had 50 talents of his 
 own placed out at interest, and if Lycurgus had 650 talents 
 entrusted to him in his own house^^ Then how great was the 
 value of the materials vested without interest in implements of 
 gold, silver, and brass, and worked up in commodities of various 
 kinds? Even in the time of the poet Aristophanes the use of 
 silver in articles of furniture was common, and it gradually 
 increased to such a point, that in order to lower the prices of 
 such vessels, when the means of the purchasers had been 
 diminished, the silver was reduced to an excessive thinness; 
 whence a comic poet speaks of vessels which weighed 4 or 2 
 drachmas, or even as little as 10 oboli®^ Every other descrip- 
 tion of household furniture {eircTrXa, aKevrj)^ even clothes and 
 women's ornaments, were estimated at the valuation, as may be 
 seen from the valuation of the property of Demosthenes; and 
 this item must have amounted to a considerable sum, for they 
 not only had conveniences for lodging, eating, and sleeping, but 
 in the houses of the wealthy they liad also establishments for 
 various kinds of trades, as for weaving, baking, &c.^°° Demos- 
 thenes' father left at his death 100 minas in furniture, cups, 
 gold, clothes, and his wife's ornaments, which, when the esti- 
 mate of the son's property was made, were included in the 
 register of taxes. The furniture of another person was worth 
 more than 20 minas. The furniture of Aristophanes, which 
 was forfeited to the state, was sold for more than 1000 
 drachmas, perhaps at less than the half of its value. Gold and 
 clothes in the dowry of persons of a middling rank were esti- 
 mated at lOminas"'^ Alcibiades' mother had jewels worth 50 
 minas. But without enumerating every trifle, and passing over 
 many statements of the orators, I shall mention only the ships, 
 the value of which cannot have been inconsiderable. 
 
 All these different items being added together, the national 
 
 ^^ Book iii. cli. 19. I '*'' Deniostli. c. Nicostrat. p. 1251, 
 
 ^■' Atheii. vi. p. 221), F, sqq. 1 15, Lys. pro Aiistoph. bonis, p. C35, 
 
 100 
 
 Couf. Xenopli. Ct:con. 9, 6. < Demo.«tli. c. Spud. p. 1030, 10
 
 492 APPROXIMATE DETERMINATION OF [bK. IV. 
 
 property, as it was estimated in the valuation, cannot 1)6 taken 
 at less than 20,000 talents, in which the monied capital, and all 
 moveables, with the exception of slaves and cattle, have evi- 
 dently been estimated at an extremely low rate at 2400 talents. 
 In every instance indeed I should make a higher estimate, but I 
 have thought it better in each successive case to take the lowest 
 which could be thought possible, in order to show that Polybius 
 had deceived himself, whatever hypothesis be adopted. 
 
 Gillies^°% who likewise w^as dissatisfied with the common 
 acceptation of this statement of Polybius, thought that the 
 landed estates only were comprised in the 5750 talents, all other 
 property having been so concealed, that an estimate of it was 
 impossible; but this directly contradicts the words of Polybius: 
 and even if we suppose that many persons concealed a portion 
 of their property, yet on the whole its amount cannot have been 
 considerable; for by reason of their law-suits and inheritances 
 the inhabitants could not have ventured to return a smaller sum 
 than they possessed; many too, in order to appear of conse- 
 quence, returned even more than they were actually worth; and, 
 generally speaking, the valuation, as the instance of Demos- 
 thenes shows, was accurately made. Least of all can I accede 
 to the idea of the writer just mentioned, that the national 
 wealth of Attica was about 12,000 talents. The number stated 
 by Polybius is too small even for the landed property alone, as 
 this might be fairly estimated at 12,000 talents. 
 
 In short, Polybius states the valuation {rifjbrjfjLa) of Attica 
 with perfect correctness at 5750 talents; but it is the valuation, 
 not the value, of the whole property: he only knew how much 
 the valuation of the whole property amounted to; but not 
 being aware of the principles upon which it had been obtained, 
 he erroneously supposed that it was the value of the whole pro- 
 perty. For the valuation taken during the archonship of Nau- 
 sinicus was, as will be shown, of a certain and fixed portion of 
 the property, which was considered as subject to taxation. This 
 portion varied in the different classes ; in the first class a fifth 
 
 ""^ Considerations upon tiiu History, ^Manners, and Character of the Greeks, 
 1>. 24.
 
 ClI. 
 
 .] 
 
 THE XATIONAT. WEALTH. 
 
 493 
 
 part was taxable^ in the inferior classes a smaller part: very 
 inconsiderable properties were doubtless not admitted into the 
 valuation at alP*'^ Consequently the national wealth was far 
 more than five times the valuation, and exclusively of the public 
 property, which was tax-free, may be estimated at 30,000 or 
 40,000 talents: the annual incomes obtained from this amount 
 of capital were at the least double what an equal sum would 
 produce at the present time, and consequently every tax was at 
 the most only half as large as it appears; or rather even smaller 
 still, for the owner of a moderate property of 5 or 6 talents 
 could hardly have consumed the returns from it upon his main- 
 tenance, without very expensive habits. 
 
 To the view which I have here taken, nothing can be 
 objected but a passage of Aristophanes, which has never yet 
 been applied to this subject, in the Ecclesiazusse'^*, which was 
 produced in Olymp. 96, 4 (b.c. 393). Euripides, probably the 
 tragic poet (but not the celebrated one, for he was dead at this 
 time), had, shortly before the representation of this play, pro- 
 posed to raise a property-tax of a fortieth, which was to produce 
 500 talents. This proposal at first gained him great popularity; 
 but afterwards, upon the rejection of the measure, the cry of 
 the people was turned against him. Why it did not succeed 
 we are not informed ; either the taxed were not able to pay^ 
 Athens not having as yet recovered from the Peloponnesian 
 war, or he had made the rate too high ; in which respect, how- 
 ever, the error cannot have been very great, for experience 
 must have already taught them what amount of property could 
 in a general way be reckoned upon as available: the former 
 supposition is, therefore, the most probable of the two. He 
 had evidently estimated the taxable capital at 20,000 talents ; 
 but that the taxable capital is in this case identical with the 
 whole property cannot be proved ; it may have only been the 
 fixed or taxable portion of it, and this may have been estimated 
 differently from the valuation in the archonship of Nausinicus; 
 
 *"^ Comp. book iv. cli. 9, near tlie 
 end. 
 
 '°* Vs. 818 sqq. An income-tax 
 
 cannot be meant, as Spanheim de U. 
 et P. N., vol. ii. p. 551, and Buraiann 
 de Vect. P. R.V. supposed.
 
 494 
 
 THE NATIONAL WKAI/IH, 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 for example, as in the valuation of Solon, which was so arranged, 
 that of the first class the whole property was returned, of the 
 second f, of the third |-: a regulation according to which, w^ith 
 about 35,000 talents of property, it would be easy to arrive at 
 a valuation nearly amounting to 20,000 talents. But it is time 
 to explain v.ith greater accuracy the system of the Athenian 
 valuation. 
 
 Chapter V. 
 
 The Valuation of Property in Attica, Early Constitution, xo'ith 
 reference to the Financial Administration. Valuation of 
 Solon, and the alterations in it up to the Archonship of 
 Nausinicus (b.c. 378). 
 
 The regulations with regard to the Athenian taxes, before the 
 time of Solon, cannot be accurately ascertained. I consider it 
 as certain, that before the changes introduced by this lawgiver 
 all the four tribes had not a share in the governing power: the 
 hopletes w^ere the ruling aristocracy; under them were the 
 cultivators [rekeovres), the goatherds {alyiKopecs), and the 
 manual labourers {apjdSec^)^'^^; the hopletes being the supreme 
 and dominant class, the cultivators paid them the sixth part of 
 the produce '"% the same portion which in India the king 
 formerly received ; and these latter were, like the penestae or 
 the clients, bondsmen or thetes in the original sense'", w^ithout 
 any property in land, which belonged solely to the hopletes. 
 The latter bore arms, when they served in war, and took their 
 attendants into the field, like the Thessalian knights ; for the 
 
 '°* Upon these classes sec my Pre- 
 face to the Catalogue of the Lectures 
 of the University of Berlin, Summer, 
 1812 (reprinted in the ^Museum Criti- 
 cura, vol. ii. p. 608). I do not find 
 myself induced to alter what I have 
 there said, since Ilullmann (Anfiinge 
 der Griechischen Geschichte, p. 239 
 sqq.) has treated this subject. Nor 
 can I, by any means, accede to Ilem- 
 sterhuis's singular explanation of 
 
 FeXioj/res, Proceres, Splendidi. Names 
 of this kind were not given to distin- 
 guish from "OTrXT^rey, 'ApyaSei?, KlyiKO- 
 peis, which all contain something defi- 
 nite and separate, no more than ol 
 TTuxels was anywhere the name of a 
 tribe fixed by the state. 
 
 'O" Plut. Sol. 13. 
 
 ^ ' These are correctly placed toge- 
 ther by Dionysius Archfeol., ii. p. 84, 
 ed. Sylb.
 
 CH. v.] VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 495 
 
 maintenance of the state in time of peace little or nothing was 
 necessary, and the wars were too inconsiderable to require an 
 artificial structure of finance. The temples and priests were 
 supported from the sacred estates, tithes, and sacrifices ; and 
 the administrators of justice were remunerated by gifts or fees 
 {yipa) upon each separate decision. The constitution of Solon 
 first, as it appears, wholly abolished bondage, which must not, 
 however, be confounded with slavery: his laws gave to all 
 freemen, that is, to all the four tribes, a share in the govern- 
 ment, apportioning their rights hov/ever according to the valua- 
 tion (rlfMrj/Ma, census); by which means the form of government 
 was brought near a democracy, without actually being one. 
 For Solon, according to the manner in which he instituted the 
 Areopagus, placed a half-aristocratical counterpoise in the 
 opposite scale ; and also by allowing the fourth class the 
 right of voting in the assembly, and a share in the jurisdiction, 
 but not permitting them to fill any . office of government, he 
 gave an influence to the upper and wealthier classes, by means 
 of which the constitution was made to resemble a timocracy, or 
 an oligarchy founded upon property. However, without wish- 
 ing to develope the whole system of Solon^s institution of classes, 
 we shall inquire into its nature in reference to the valuation 
 and the public services. 
 
 Solon made four classes {ri/jLrjfjuara, riXr])^^^, a number 
 afterwards adopted by Plato in his work on Laws^"^; the 
 methods, according to which they fixed them, were however 
 very different. The first class was the pentacosiomedimni ; 
 that is to say, those who received 500 measures, either dry or 
 liquid, from their lands, medimni of dry, and metretse of liquid 
 measure. For the second class he took those who received 300 
 measures, and could afford to keep a horse, viz., a war-horse 
 (iTTTToy iroXe^iLarrjpLo^), to which was added another for a 
 servant, and they must also necessarily have required a yoke of 
 animals: this class was called knights [Itttttj^, LTrirdBa TeXovvres), 
 
 i*"* The latter expression is used by 
 Harpocration and Suidas in v. Ittttcis, 
 
 and by others; the former is very 
 common. 
 
 '°» V. p. 744, e. vi. p. 755, E.
 
 496 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 Qbk. IV. 
 
 The third class are the zeugitte {^evyLTat), and their valuation 
 is called the valuation of the zeugitte (^evyiacov reXetv); by 
 which, however, is not to be understood a particular tax upon 
 cattle used in ploughing, as might be supposed from the account 
 o-iven by Pollux. Their name is derived from keeping a yoke 
 (^€1)709), whether of common mules, or of working-horses or 
 oxen. Their income is stated in general at 200 measures of 
 dry and Uquid measure. The last class is the thetes, whose 
 valuation was less than that of the zeugitcc"*'. "The pentaco- 
 siomedimni/' says Pollux, "^^ expended upon the pubUc weal 
 [avrfKiaKov is to BrjfjLoacov) 1 talent, the second 30 minas, the 
 third 10 minas, and the thetes nothing^ ".'^ 
 
 Thus far we have followed the most authentic accordant 
 statements. Some grammarians, however, only mention three 
 classes (ra^et?), and entirely omit the zeugitse^^^ which is evi- 
 dently erroneous, as well as the statement of Aristotle^ ^% or of 
 some grammarian or copyist who has interpolated the words in 
 his text, which makes the knights the third, and the zeugitas 
 the second class, in direct opposition to the testimonies of all 
 
 ^-" Pint. Sol. 18, ^vhere, iii speaking j 
 of the third class, he is made, by an | 
 en-or of the transcriber, to say, oh \ 
 fierpov rjv o-vva^(f)OT€pcov TpiaKocridiv \ 
 instead of diaKoalcov, as Henry Stephens ; 
 has rightly corrected from Pollux : 
 (Tvvafi(f)oT€pa}v means both dry and j 
 liquid measure : as, for example, Lex. 
 Seg. p. 298, in TrevTaKocnoix^bipvoi: 
 TrevraKoaia perpa crvvdp<pa) ^rjpa Kai 
 vypd. Plutarch gives the right num- : 
 bar in the Comparison of Aristides and 
 Cato, cap. 1, with the remark, that the | 
 means of individuals were at that time 
 still moderate. Also see Pollux vii. 
 129, 130. Suid. in 'nnras and InTrels, 
 Photius in 'nrncis, where in the first 
 article 'nrTre^s and Innds are absurdly 
 stated to be ditferent classes, Argum. 
 Aristoph. Equit., Schol. Plat. Ruhnk. 
 p. 184, Etym. in d-qTcia, Nicephoms 
 Gregor. ad Synes., Zonaras in v. e/c 
 Tip.r)pdT<>>Vf Hai-pocrat. in 'nrTras, who 
 
 all give the same order, the latter re- 
 ferring to Aristotle's State of Athens, 
 also Schol. Thiicyd. iii. 16; Hesychius 
 (in v. iTTTras) is mutilated : also, see 
 Lex. Seg. pp. 260, 261, 267, 269, and 
 concerning ^evyiaiov Pollux ^^ii. 130, 
 132 ; Suid. Phot. Etym. Lex. Seg. pp. 
 260, 261 ; and Hesychius. In several 
 of these passages it is falsely written 
 ^evyrjo-iov. That C^vyos generally 
 means a yoke of mules, we learn from 
 the orators, e. g. Isseus de Dicseog. 
 Hered. p. 116, de Philoctem. Hered. 
 p. 140. The Etymologist and Photius 
 in V. (evyos, and Lex. Seg. p. 260, 
 when combined, refer this expression 
 to all the three kinds of animals. 
 
 ''' Pollux is followed by Schol. 
 Plat. ed. Ruhnk. p. 184. 
 
 "^ Etym. and Photius in v. (fvyiaiov, 
 Schol. Aristoph. Equit. 624. 
 
 ''3 Polit. ii. 10.
 
 CH. v.] VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 49/ 
 
 ancient writers''*, who invariably mention the knights after the 
 pentacosiomedimni, and above all to the law which will be 
 presently quoted. Nor can any argument be drawn from a fact 
 recorded in an inscription upon the Acropolis' '% that Anthemion, 
 the son of Diphilus, of the class of thetes {6r]rcKov reXo^), was 
 immediately raised to the class of knights; for a person might 
 easily become on a sudden so rich by inheritance, as to be 
 transferred from the lowest into the second class. Suidas, 
 indeed, ascribes 400 measures to the knights, which appears to 
 be an error of the transcriber, rather than of the author; for 
 the scholiasts of x\ristophanes and Demosthenes"^ who repeat 
 the text of Suidas, only differ from him in giving the correct 
 number, viz., 300 instead of 400 ; therefore Reiske deserves no 
 attention when, by an alteration of the common reading, he 
 wishes to make Plutarch say, in the life of Solon, that the 
 knights had 400 and the zeugitse 300 measures. Synesius"^ 
 even calls the second class triacosiomedimni, instead of the 
 usual name of knights. 
 
 Nevertheless I venture to reject the statement preserved by 
 all writers, that the number of measures for the zeugitse was 
 200, not however because it is incredible that all were thetes 
 who had less than 200 measures : a stronger argument against 
 the correctness of the statement than the last would be, that the 
 difference between the 200 measures of the zeugitee and the 
 300 of the knights, is too small in comparison with that between 
 the knights and the pentacosiomedimni; but my reason for 
 rejecting it is, that a law preserved in Demosthenes"^ leads to a 
 different conclusion. This law fixes the allowance which any 
 person of the three upper classes was to make to an heiress in 
 the lowest class, if, being her nearest relation, he did not choose 
 to marry her. The pentacosiomedimnus was to give her 500 
 drachmas, and the knight 300; thus both were to give the 
 same number of drachmas as they received measures : the 
 
 "* For example, Thuc. iii. 16. I ^'^ De Insomn. p. 140, B. 
 
 *'^ Pollux viii. 131. ^'^ Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1067 sqq. 
 
 "^ Scliol. Aristoph. Eqiiit. 624. ! comp. Harpocration in v. Or/Tes and 
 Schol. Demosth. vol. ii. p. 85, ed. j cTrt'SiKos-, Diod. xii. 18, 
 Reiske. I 
 
 2 K
 
 498 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 zeugites^ however, was to give only 150 drachmas. I am 
 persuaded, therefore, that the property of the zeugitae only sup- 
 posed an income of 150 measures: whoever had less than 150 
 measures belonged to th^ thetes : whoever had between 150 
 and 300 to the zeugitae ; from 300 to 500 to the knights ; and 
 from 500 and upwards to the pentacosiomedimni. 
 
 Modern writers relate with great complacency the amount 
 of taxes which, according to the statement of Pollux, these 
 classes paid to the state, without being aware of the absurdity 
 involved in it"^ The question is^ what notion shall we form 
 of these imposts of a talent, of 30 minas, and 10 minas ? Are 
 we to suppose that they were a regular tax which was paid into 
 the public treasury ? If so, the annual revenue of Athens 
 would necessarily have l)een very large, whereas it at no time 
 amounted to more than 2000 talents ; unless we assume with 
 Salmasius that Athens had a yearly revenue of 6000 talents, of 
 w^hich 2000 were derived from the sources which Aristophanes 
 enumerates in the Wasps, and 4000 from the valuations of the 
 citizens ; an assertion which is too groundless and absurd to 
 deserve a moment's attention. Or were those sums to be 
 employed for the liturgies? The expression agrees very well 
 W' ith this hypothesis, but it is inconceivable that the state should 
 have fixed the exact sum of money which each person was to 
 expend in his own liturgy: how much was to be performed in 
 each liturgy w^as exactly defined, e.g., how many singers or 
 flute-players the choregus was to furnish, how he was to main- 
 tain, how to ornament them, and in like manner with the other 
 liturgies : to the state it was indifferent what sum each indivi- 
 dual liturgy cost. One person might, by good management, 
 supply at a small expense, what another, from inexperience, 
 had only been able to provide at a large outlay; if, therefore, 
 the government fixed any determinate standard, it failed in 
 attaining its object; not to mention that in the age of Solon 
 the liturgies could not have been so expensive, and there is no 
 
 "^ Also Budaeus (de asse et paitibus 
 ejus V. p. 530, Gryph.) both upon this 
 point and upon that of the valuation 
 of 6000 talents, falls into great confu- 
 
 sion; for, perceiving that he is at 
 variance with himself, he searches, 
 though unsuccessfully, for some expla- 
 nation.
 
 CH. V.l VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 499 
 
 -■ / 
 
 question as to subsequent times. Or, lastly, shall we suppose 
 that this scale was for the regulation of the extraordinary taxes ? 
 An extraordinary tax, like the eisphora w^hich w^as first levied 
 in the 88th Olympiad (b.c. 428), could not have been so high 
 in the time of Solon, as the sums stated by Pollux. Again, the 
 method of its imposition could not have been such that all 
 persons in the same class paid the same sum, for example, that 
 each pentacosiomedimnus contributed a talent, whether he 
 received 500 or 5000 medimni, a regulation which would have 
 been manifestly absurd : neither can we suppose that all persons 
 were excluded from the payment of this tax, who were not able 
 to contribute 10 minas. Is it possible to believe that all were 
 thetes {capite censi) who did not pay taxes to the amount of 10 
 minas ; that 10 minas was the smallest amount of tax required 
 of the citizens, and this too from landed property alone ? 
 Lastly, in the imposition of extraordinary taxes, it was never 
 determinately fixed what the rate of contribution was to be 
 both for the actual levy and all future occasions. On the 
 contrary, the rate was appointed according to the sum required. 
 If the amount was great, the scale was higher ; if small, it was 
 less. 
 
 It is thus impossible to ascertain what this large tax, of 
 which Pollux speaks, is to be referred to ; but in order to con- 
 vince the most incredulous of the total want of foundation in 
 this account, I will add the following short explanation. In the 
 time of Solon the medimnus of corn sold for a drachma'*^; if 
 the price of a metretes of oil was higher, wine on the other hand 
 was cheaper ^'^^; so that upon an average, a measure of products 
 of the soil cannot be reckoned at more than a drachma. The 
 pentacosiomedimnus was consequently valued according to his 
 landed property, at an income of 500 drachmas ; and are we to 
 suppose that a talent was to be paid out of that sum, which is 
 the twelfth part of the receipts, and for the others the same, 
 according to their respective proportion ? Or is the seed-corn, 
 and not the whole produce, meant by the 500, 3G0, and 150 
 measures, as in the Mosaic law, in which the rates Avere fixed 
 
 Book i. cU. 15. '^' Book i. ch. ICi, 
 
 2 K 2
 
 500 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. [bK. IV. 
 
 according to this standard? Of this, however, no ancient 
 author says one word, whatever inaccurate writers on early- 
 history may assert ; liquid measures are moreover expressly- 
 included, in which no seed-corn exists ; and again, this quantity 
 of seed-corn would have been too considerable : for in later 
 times, Alcibiades, who was unquestionably a pentacosiomedim- 
 nus, possessed only 300 plethra of land; nor can any one 
 imagine that all were thetes who did not use 150 measures of 
 seed-corn for their lands ? In whatever way we look at it, the 
 statement of Pollux fails. Is it then to be absolutely rejected ? 
 or does it contain a concealed truth? Unquestionably; but it 
 has been made almost indiscernible by a gross misapprehension 
 of its meaning. 
 
 We have next to consider how Solon's institution of classes 
 was arranged with regard to the duties of the citizens. As the 
 rights differed according to the classes, so did the burdens. 
 Among these, the first was the obligation to military service in 
 its different gradations. The thetes were said, in a lost passage 
 of Aristophanes, to have performed no military service^^**, like 
 the lowest class of the Romans : although this may have been 
 the case in ancient times, it may be assumed, without hesitation, 
 that they soon served as light-armed soldiers (-v/rtXot), and as 
 sailors: they were, indeed, sometimes used as hoplitse upon an 
 emergency'", as well as many even of the resident aliens; but 
 since they had no obligation of this kind, it was doubtless 
 necessary for the state to arm them on these occasions. Thucy- 
 dides"'^ mentions hoplitse, who were of the class of thetes, but 
 opposes them to the regular hoplitcP, from the list {oTrXlrac itc 
 KardXoyov). The zeugita? evidently composed the mass of 
 those who were bound to serve as hoplitee. Above them came 
 the knights, whose name alone shows that their duty was to 
 serve as cavalry, even if they were not at all times bound to 
 hold themselves in readiness. Of the pentacosiomedimni we 
 
 '2^ Ilarpociat. in v. BrjTes, comp. 
 Phot, in V. 8r)T€vs. 
 
 ^^ Antiphon ap. Harpocrat. ut sup. 
 contains an indication of this in the 
 
 words, Tovs 6^Tas anapras onXiras 
 Troirja-at. 
 ^'* vi. 43.
 
 CH. v.] 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 501 
 
 know nothing : but it is evident that persons of this class must 
 in general have filled the situations of commanders, as well as 
 that of trierarch, which was also a military service; the other 
 liturgies were also probably performed according to the valua- 
 tions of the classes, although the distribution of them is not 
 known. Lastly, I entertain no doubt that when the valuation 
 was taken, a scale was at the same time fixed, according to 
 which an extraordinary tax was raised whenever the occasion 
 occurred ; but there was no regular collection at the time when 
 these assessments were made, since otherwise we should un- 
 questionably have more determinate information upon that 
 point'"; and the first introduction of the property tax, at so 
 late a period as in the Peloponnesian war, shows how unfre- 
 quent and extraordinary were the occasions on which imposts 
 of this kind had previously been levied. 
 
 The expression to pay a valuation [reXelv reXo^;) is indeed of 
 so frequent occurrence, that we might infer from it that there 
 existed a tax which was regularly raised, especially since the 
 more definite expression is sometimes used oi paying the valua- 
 tion of a knight or of a zeugites (iTTTrdSa and iTTTrcKov reXelv, 
 i^evylaiov reXecv, eh lirirdha reKelv) : it is to be observed, 
 however, that the valuation of the thetes, and their paying a 
 valuation '^^ {OrjroKov ri\o9, Otjtlkov reXelv) are also mentioned, 
 and yet it is clear that they paid no tax, even according to the 
 statement of Pollux. The poll-tax which was paid at Potidaea, 
 by the persons who were destitute of property'^", was a mode 
 of levying money entirely peculiar to that, town, and not derived 
 from the mother-country, and was moreover used only for 
 extraordinary taxes. This idiom, however, admits of an easy 
 explanation ; for the same word which signifies valuation, also 
 means a rank or class, and the words which mean to pay a 
 
 '■^5 EvenBudgeus ut sup. p. 534, was 
 aware that no regular direct tax (tri- 
 butum) was levied at Athens. 
 
 ^*^ See concerning this expression, 
 passing over the grammarians, De- 
 mosth. c. Timocr. p. 745, 13. Isaeus 
 de Apollod. Hered. p. 185, an ancient 
 
 law in Demosth. c. Macart. p. 1067, 28. 
 Inscript. ap. Poll. viii. 131. Dinarch. 
 c. Aristog. p. 80, and many other 
 
 '^^ Pseud-Aristot. (Econ, 2, 5, ed. 
 Schneid.
 
 502 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 valuation, also stand for merely belonging to a class^^^. Besides, 
 the payment or performance of a valuation {reXecv to Te\o<;) 
 does not mean the payment of a fixed regular impost, but the 
 fulfilment of all those duties which were imposed upon a class 
 according to its valuation, particularly military service and 
 liturgies, together with the extraordinary property taxes. 
 Xenophon^" mentions every expense which the state required 
 at the hands of a citizen, and which could oppress him, but he 
 is silent concerning a regular duty, although he makes use of an 
 expression which must have instantly reminded him of it, if any- 
 thing of the kind had existed. The only circumstance that 
 could justify us in considering the valuation-taxes as ordinary 
 ones, would be the occurrence of some passage in which they 
 are distinctly opposed to the liturgies and the extraordinary 
 taxes ; but I have sought for one in vain. Where Antiphon^^'' 
 opposes the payment of the duties [KaraTodivac ra reXr]) to 
 the choregia, a Mytilensean is speaking of his father, who was 
 one of those deprived of their estates ; but these, although they 
 paid to the Athenians a rent of 2 minas for each lot'^^, also 
 
 ^^^ Theuce is avbpas reXelv, is Boico- 
 Tovs TiXeeiv, ill the same sense Herod, 
 vi. 108. Thence reXos of a division of 
 troops, particularly of cavalry. Censeri 
 is used in Latin in the same way as 
 reXeij/ in Greek. 
 
 ''^^ GEcou. 2, 6, en be kol ttju irokiv 
 aladdvoiiaL to. fxkv fjh-q aoi npocrraTTOV- 
 (rav [xeyaka reXeii/, In'o-oTpocpias re (for 
 the cavalry at festivals) kol xoprjyias 
 Kai yvjJLvacriapx'-o.s kol TrpocrraTeias (an 
 obscure expression which cannot sig- 
 nify the patronage of the resident 
 aliens, but may refer to the iarlaais, 
 which was also called (pvXapx^a, see 
 Wolf, p. Ixxxviii.) ^v fie 817 7rdXe/iOS 
 yivTjTai, old' on kol TpLr)papx^cis pnaOovs 
 KOL elrrcpopas Toaavras (Toi npoara^ov- 
 (711/, ocraj (jv ov pabicos xmoicreLS. The 
 meaning of the word re'Xoy is very well : 
 explained in Lex. Seg. p. 308, TeKrj : j 
 ov fjiovov TO. Tols TeXcovaty KaralBaWo- 
 p-eva, dWa Koi to. dva\o)paTa. Xa/i/3a- ■ 
 VfTai Kai inl dnijpTKTpiuco npayp-ari r/ | 
 
 €py(o T] TToXe'/xo). Hence also areXjys 
 and are'Xeia of the exemption from 
 liturgies, and noXvTeKrjs. Conf. Phot, 
 in V. TeXos. 
 
 '^^ De Herod, csede p. 744. 'ETret 
 fi' vp.€7s Tovs qItlovs rovTcav €KoXdaaT€, 
 ev ols ovK i(f)aiv€TO ciyv 6 epos Trarfjpj 
 To7s S' dXXoLS MvTiXijvaiois abeiav e'fio)- 
 Kare oi/ceii/ Tr]U acperepav avrtov (since 
 they allowed them to hold their land 
 on condition of paying a rent), ovk 
 e<TTiv 6 Ti vcrrepou avrca fjpdprrjrat ra 
 ip(o TTarpl, old' on ov TreTroirjTai nop 
 deovTcov, oL»S' rjS nvos Xeuovpylas rj 
 TToXis evberjs yeyevrjTai ovre fj vperepa 
 (sic lege) ovre rj MvTiXT)vaiciv, dXXa 
 ical xopriy'ias exoprjyei (that is, in the 
 island of Mytilene, divided among 
 cleruchi) koi TeXrj KareTidei (to the 
 Athenians). 
 
 ^^' See book iii. ch. 18, concerning 
 this individual comp. book iii. ch. 16, 
 note 422.
 
 CH. V,] VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 503 
 
 performed liturgies for their own community. Again, the only- 
 reason which Plato gives in the Laws for the four-fold division 
 of classes in his state is, that the offices of government, the 
 eisphora (or extraordinary tax), and the distributions {Biavo/j,ai), 
 could be arranged according to them ; and, lastly, to what pur- 
 pose Athens should, in the early times, have raised a yearly 
 tax, when a part of the public revenue, and particularly of the 
 money received from the mines, was divided among the citizens, 
 it is difficult to comprehend. 
 
 A tax according to the valuation can therefore be only sup- 
 posed to have occurred upon extremely rare occasions under 
 Solon^s institution of classes. The imposition of taxes was only 
 a subordinate consideration j the chief objects were the obligation 
 to military service, the liturgies, and the apportioning of the rights 
 of government. But in order to comprehend how the scale was 
 arranged in each case as it occurred, we must premise an observa- 
 tion upon the meaning of the word valuation {TifjbrjfjLa). Custom 
 has comprehended under this term a collection of very different 
 ideas. Every estimate of the value of any article is so called; 
 the estimate of property, the assessment of a fine, the estimate 
 of a tax; in short, everything that is valued. But a part of the 
 property, which serves to regulate the apportioning of taxes, 
 might be, with equal propriety, called by that name. Solon 
 gave to each of the classes, except the thetes, a fixed valuation, 
 or timema, and even the classes themselves are so called {rer- 
 rapa TLfjur/fMara) in Plato and in most other writers who mention 
 them. This valuation, which we will call the taxable capital, is 
 not absolutely identical with the estimate of property, and is 
 very different from the tax. The grammarians had not formed 
 any idea of timema as taxable capital, for they sometimes con- 
 found it with the estimate of property; while Pollux considered 
 it as the tax, and thus fell into a most important error. No 
 rational explanation can be given of Solon^s institution of 
 classes, as far as it regards the direct taxation, but by embracing 
 this view of the question. When so considered, however, we 
 recognise his wisdom. Solon estimated the value of the me- 
 dimnus at a drachma''^ Now if he had wished to ascertain 
 
 Plut. Sol. 23.
 
 504 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. [bK. IV. 
 
 the landed property of each class from the produce, his only 
 
 way would have been to consider the number of medimni, or 
 their equivalent in liquid measure, as the produce accruing from 
 the land, taking however as his standard only the net proceeds, 
 which were received as rent. We must therefore consider these 
 500, 300, 150 measures as net profit, obtained from what an 
 estate yielded as rent; a course which was the more natural, as 
 many estates, particularly those of the wealthy, were let by 
 their masters to thetes or to bond-slaves, as we are expressly 
 informed with regard to the thetes ^^\ That the rent was com- 
 puted in kind, and not in money, is what might have been 
 naturally expected. This practice indeed frequently occurs, 
 even in later times; nor would any other method have been 
 possible at that period, on account of the small quantity of 
 money in circulation. 
 
 The next question to be considered is, at what per-centage of 
 the value of the property did Solon fix this net produce ? We 
 are informed that rents were low in ancient times; so late as in 
 the speeches of Iseeus we read of an estate which was let at 8 per 
 cent.^^* We have therefore good reason for assuming that 
 Solon, whose intention it must have been to encourage low 
 rents, took the net proceeds as the twelfth part of the value of 
 the land, or 8^ per cent., and according to that scale fixed the 
 property of a pentacosiomedimnus at a talent, that is, at a 
 twelfth of his income. According to the same calculation, the 
 landed property of a knight amounted to 3600 drachmas, of a 
 zeugites to 1800. The principle of this arrangement is per- 
 fectly correct; for the smaller is the amount of the incomes, 
 the less in proportion must the state take from an equally large 
 part of the income of a citizen: as every man must first pro- 
 vide maintenance for himself and his family, and the poor are 
 oppressed to a greater degree than the rich, if they are taxed in 
 the same proportion, and at the same rate. Now this principle, 
 so well adapted to the philanthropic lawgiver, may have been 
 put in operation by Solon in two manners; either by the infe- 
 rior class paying a smaller proportion of their property than the 
 
 ^3' Pint. Sol. KS. 13^ Book i. ch. 24.
 
 CH. v.] 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 505 
 
 superior, for example, the first ^ per cent., the second i per 
 cent., the third -I- per cent.; or by the taxable capital being so 
 rated, that in the lower classes only a part of the property was 
 considered as taxable. The first method renders the arrange- 
 ment difiicult and complicated; the other is far more intel- 
 ligible: the government knows the sum total of the taxable 
 capital, and the amount of its own necessities, and it can be 
 seen at once what part of the taxable capital must be demanded. 
 This regulation appears to have been invariably followed at 
 Athens, after it had been once taught by Solon. The pentacosio- 
 medimnus was, according to his regulation of the classes, entered 
 in the register with his w^hole productive landed property, the 
 knight with five-sixths, the zeugites with five-ninths of it; but 
 all paid the same part of the taxable capital when a duty was 
 imposed. Supposing that the whole valuation, or the sum of 
 all the taxable capitals, amounted to 3000 talents, and that the 
 state was in need of 60 talents, a fiftieth would have been 
 raised, and the division was in that case made as the following 
 table shows: — 
 
 Classes. 
 
 Incomes. 
 
 Landed Estates. 
 
 Taxable Capital. 
 
 Tax of a 50th. 
 
 Pentacos. 
 
 Knights 
 
 Zeugitse 
 
 500 drachmas 
 300 drachmas 
 150 drachmas 
 
 6000 drachmas 
 3600 drachmas 
 1800 drachmas 
 
 6000 drachmas 
 3000 drachmas 
 
 1000 drachmas 
 
 _ 
 
 120 drachmas 
 60 drachmas 
 20 drachmas 
 
 A more beautiful division is scarcely conceivable. It should 
 be observed, however, that it is possible, or even probable, that 
 there existed some difference in the amount of taxes in the 
 same class. We may suppose that, adhering still to the 
 standard of property, they imposed the tax in such a manner 
 that in each class the taxable capital was fixed according to the 
 same proportion; as is shown by the following table: —
 
 506 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 IV. 
 
 Classes. 
 
 Incomes. 
 
 Landed 
 Property. 
 
 Of which was 
 Taxable. 
 
 Taxable 
 Capital. 
 
 Tax of a 50th. 
 
 Pentacosio- 
 medimni. 
 
 1000 dr. 
 750 dr. 
 500 dr. 
 
 12000 dr. 
 9000 dr. 
 6000 dr. 
 
 The whole 
 The whole 
 The whole 
 
 12000 dr. 
 9000 dr. 
 6000 dr. 
 
 240 dr. 
 180 dr. 
 120 dr. 
 
 Knights. 
 
 450 dr. 
 400 dr. 
 300 dr. 
 
 5400 dr. 
 4800 dr. 
 3600 dr. 
 
 Five sixths 
 Five sixths 
 Five sixths 
 
 4500 dr. 
 4000 dr. 
 3000 dr. 
 
 90 dr. 
 80 dr. 
 60 dr. 
 
 Zeugitae. 
 
 250 dr. 
 200 dr. 
 160 dr. 
 
 3000 dr. ' Five ninths 
 2400 dr. Five ninths 
 1800 dr. Five ninths 
 
 16661 dr. 
 1333i dr. 
 1000 dr. 
 
 33i dr. 
 26| dr. 
 20 dr. 
 
 Under Solon's institution of classes, the land in cultivation 
 was alone estimated: but when in the Peloponnesian war the 
 property taxes became frequent, it was no longer possible that 
 the landed proprietors should be exclusively taxed, particularly 
 as this was the very period at which they were in the most dis- 
 tressed situation; the former scale had also ceased to be suit- 
 able, on account of the increase of wealth. The menace in the 
 Knights of Aristophanes'^* is not intelligible, unless we suppose 
 that moveables were also subject to taxation. Cleon threatens 
 a person with having him registered among the rich, in order 
 that he might be ruined by property taxes ; and the proposal of 
 Euripides, which was made a short time before Olymp. 96, 4 
 (b.c. 393), to raise 500 talents by imposing a tax of a fortieth, 
 is only compatible with a taxable capital, which not only 
 embraced all moveable property, but in which the rates of the 
 classes were also wholly changed : for if it had been regulated 
 upon the same principles as the valuation of Solon, it would 
 require 20,000 citizens, nearly all of the rank of pentacosio- 
 medimni, for the taxable capital to amount to so large a sum : 
 on the other hand, a taxable capital of this amount might have 
 (easily existed, if all the moveable and immoveable property 
 were added together, and the taxable part of it taken according 
 to the principles of Solon. 
 
 The ancient names were in the mean time retained; not 
 
 Vs. 923.
 
 CH. v.] VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 50? 
 
 only in Olymp. 88, 1 (b.c. 428)'^% when the first tax was 
 levied^ but even in later times, we meet with pentacosiomedimni 
 and knights as distinct ranks. In the play of Aristophanes 
 (Olymp. 88, 4, B.C. 425) that bears their name, the knights are 
 represented as a class of the people, and not merely as horse- 
 men, as they were in the time of Demosthenes ; and even in 
 Olymp. 93, 3 (b.c, 406) we meet with a distinct mention of 
 the two superior ranks '^^. It cannot be proved with certainty, 
 as far as I am aware, that these classes existed after the archon- 
 ship of Euclid (Olymp. 94, 2, b.c. 403). In the archonship of 
 Nausinicus (b.c. 378) they were unquestionably suppressed, if 
 they were then in existence. Yet I am rather inclined to sup- 
 pose that, like so many other institutions, they were abolished 
 by the changes introduced in the archonship of Euclid. The 
 pentacosiomedimnus mentioned in Lysias'^^ may have been 
 taken from the times anterior to Euclid. In Demosthenes^^' 
 the four ranks only occur in an ancient law, which was perhaps 
 still in force with regard to heiresses, but its original meaning 
 must have been altered, and the names could only have referred 
 to new classes which had been introduced in the place of those 
 instituted by Solon. 
 
 If any one passage could make it probable that the institu- 
 tion of Solon remained until the year of Nausinicus, it would 
 be that of Isseus'***, in which it is stated that " ApoUodorus, the 
 adopted father of the defendant, did not act so dishonourably as 
 Pronapes, who only returned a small valuation, and yet as if he 
 had a knight^s valuation laid claim to offices of government.^' 
 Pronapes therefore entered himself at a lower valuation, but he 
 was a candidate for offices which required the property of a 
 knight. At what time however he did this we know not. The 
 orator may be speaking of ancient times, anterior to the year of 
 
 '^•^ Thucyd. iii. 16, in this year the 
 names of the classes in question occur. 
 '■^7 Xenoph. Hell. i. 6, 17- 
 ^^" Harpocrat. in v. TrcvraKoa-iofie- 
 
 Reiske has wholly misunderstood this 
 passage. The words are, /cat firjv koI 
 avTOS ^AnoWobcopos ov;^, oycnrfp ETpo- 
 mnijs, aTTeypdyj/aTO fxev rip.Tjpa p-iKpov, 
 
 bifivoi. ; ojy Imrdda 8i reXcov apx^iv rj^lov ras 
 
 ^^^ In Macart. p. 1067 sq! apxds. 
 
 '•" De Apollod. Hered. p. 185. i
 
 508 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 [bk. IV, 
 
 Euclid. If this be not conceded, I may assume that although 
 the ancient classes were abolished in the archonship of Euclid, 
 new ones were instituted, one of which again bore the general 
 name of knights, which was given to a class of the people in 
 many states besides Athens. It is to be also observed, that 
 there is another difficulty in this passage, viz. that a knight^s 
 valuation was requisite for eligibility to offices of government. 
 According to the constitution of Solon, these were only open 
 to citizens of a certain valuation, and the thetes were excluded, 
 as we learn from Aristotle and others. The archons, at the 
 time when Aristides filled this office (Olymp. 73, 1, b.c. 488), 
 were still chosen by lot out of the pentacosiomedimni'*': hence 
 the question at the Anacrisis of the nine archons, and in general 
 jn all high situations, " whether the candidate had the valuation, 
 or paid the taxes'";" that is, again, whether he performed the 
 liturgies, paid the extraordinary taxes, and was regularly regis- 
 tered in the class to which the archon was required to belong. 
 In the same manner it was necessary for the treasurers of the 
 goddess and the gods to be pentacosiomedimni'". But Aris- 
 tides, after the battle of Plataeee, gave all the Athenians the 
 right of admission to offices of government'**: and therefore in 
 the case of these treasurers we cannot suppose that this restric- 
 tion was owing to the highness of their office; but that, as the 
 management of money was entrusted to them, they were still 
 obliged, for the sake of security, to prove to a fixed amount of 
 property. Dinarchus reckons this question respecting the 
 valuation among the antiquated customs of the state, nor is 
 there any mention of it in the speech of Demosthenes against 
 Eubulides; although indeed this is not a conclusive proof, for it 
 might have been there omitted compatibly with the object of 
 
 >^i Plut. Aristid. 1. 
 
 ^■'^ Et TO Ti^rjfid ioTLV avTtOf et to. 
 riKr] reXei, Pollux viii. 86, Dinarch. c. 
 Aristog. p. 86, who p. 87, by reXos evi- 
 dently means the extraordinary tax 
 {(la<f>opd). The serving in war is in 
 this place excepted from the reXos, 
 and on accomit of its importance is 
 
 particularly inquired after, which can- 
 not seem strange, since the t(\os only 
 determined the species of arms, and 
 from that it could be ascertained 
 whether the individual was present in 
 the field. 
 
 '*3 Bookii. ch. 5. 
 
 '" Plutarch. Aristid. 22.
 
 CH. v.] 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY, 
 
 509 
 
 the speaker' '\ Theogenes, of noble birth, but of small means, 
 was king-archon in the age of Demosthenes' '^ Lastly, the 
 needy and infirm man (dBvvaros), who is represented as speak- 
 ing in Lysias, manifestly belonged to the lowest class of per- 
 sons entirely destitute of property, since he claims the allow- 
 ance for the poor from the state '^^ This man nevertheless 
 asserts, that if his body was not defective, his adversaries would 
 not be able to hinder him from casting lots for the dignity of 
 one of the nine archons, and accuses his fate of depriving him 
 of the highest honours'*^; meaning the infirmity of his body, 
 
 ^^5 P. 1319, 20 sqq. 
 
 ^*« Orat. c. Neser. p. 1369, 17- 
 
 "' See Lysias Trepi rov ddvv. p. ^A3, 
 
 sqq. 
 
 ^*^ p. 749, KaiTOL el tovto Treiaei rivas 
 vfxcov, CO /SovXt), tl fjLC koj\v€1 Kkr)pov(r6aL 
 TOiv ivvea apxovroiv ; and afterwards p. 
 750, ov yap drjnov rov avTov vfiels }i€V 
 lis 8vvdixevov d<paipr]cr€a6€ to 8t86p.€vov, 
 ol de (his opponents) w? dSwdrov ovra 
 Kk-qpovadai KcoXvcrov(Tiv . p. 756, eTreiBf) 
 ycip, <B ^ovXrj, Twv p-eyiarcov dp^av 6 
 daificov dTreaTeprjcrev T)p.ds, and after- 
 wards, TTQiS OVU OVK CIV SeiXaiOTOTOS €^T)V, 
 
 ft Ta>v /xeV KaWicTTOiv Koi fxeyicTTCOV did 
 rffv (rvfx(f)opdu dmcTTep'qp.evos iir)v. 
 Petit iii. 2, on the law concerning the 
 Anacrisis of the archons (p. 239 sqq. 
 of the old edition) shows, that freedom 
 from all bodily defects was necessary 
 for the office of archon ; doubtless on 
 account of the sacrifices which he had 
 to perform. But it is singular that he 
 did not perceive that, according to 
 Aristides, there might have been an 
 archon out of every class of property, 
 and should imagine that the law of 
 Aristides was repealed ; of which I do 
 not find any proof. In ancient times 
 the archons were chosen not by lot, 
 but by cheirotonia, as may be inferred 
 from the intricate passage in the ora- 
 tion against Neaera, p. 1370, 19. [The 
 author mentions in the Addenda, 
 " that he had inferred from the ora- 
 tion against Nesera that in ancient 
 
 times the archons were chosen by chei- 
 rotonia." He then proceeds to say, 
 that "it hardly deserves mentioning, 
 that what the orator asserts of the 
 king-archon in the democracy, which, 
 according to common report he com- 
 mences with Theseus, may be taken 
 generally of the ancient election of 
 the nine archons. In order however 
 to reconcile this assertion with the ap- 
 parently inconsistent account of the 
 election of the archons by lot from 
 among the pentacosiomedimni (see 
 above p. 508), it must be remembered, 
 that the election of the archons was 
 frequently changed with the progress 
 of freedom and equality. The office 
 of king was after the time of Codrus 
 changed into that of archon, by merely 
 compelling the king to give an account 
 of his official proceedings (Pausan. iv. 
 5), but the office remained by inherit- 
 ance in the royal family of the Nelei- 
 dae or Codridae. The next step was 
 the limitation of the time of holding 
 the office to ten years. It remained 
 nevertheless in the ancient royal family 
 until the time of Eryxias, who was the 
 last in the uninterrupted series of the 
 Medontidae, according to the testi- 
 mony of ancient writers. The annual 
 archons which then succeeded were 
 chosen by cheirotonia from among the 
 nobility, in which the ancient royal 
 family was included (tjpfdtja-av i^ 
 EiViraTpibcop Eiiseb. Chron» p. 41), of
 
 510 
 
 VALUATION OF PROPERTY. 
 
 [bK. IV. 
 
 which impeded him from standing for the office of arch on, and 
 not the want of property. Accordingly we can at the most 
 refer the statement of Isaeus to situations such as those of the 
 treasurers, for whom a certain valuation was agreeably to reason 
 always requisite, in order that the state might have a pledge of 
 their honesty^ ^^ 
 
 Chapter VI. 
 
 Public Registers in Attica, Register of Lands, General 
 Register of Property, 
 
 For the purposes of the public valuation, registers (aTroypacj^ai) 
 were generally used in Greece, as was the case in Egypt and 
 the kingdom of Persia, which in different places were arranged 
 according to different principles. 
 
 The method adopted in Attica was that each person valued 
 his own property, and returned the amount; after which they 
 were doubtless, as in Potidsea, subject to the check of a counter- 
 valuation {v7roTLfir,(TL9Y'\ In early times, however, there was 
 
 which series Solon the Codrides is to 
 be considered the last (cf. Plutarch. 
 Solon. 14, iOP^Ot} apxoiv; alperos is the 
 same xf'poToi^'jros). Solon then sub- 
 stituted a timocracy in the place of the 
 ancient aristocracy, and from this time 
 eligibility no longer depended upon 
 birth, but upon property, and the 
 archons were chosen by cheirotonia 
 (Aristot. Polit. ii. 9, where the words 
 dpxovTcov alpco-is should be thus under- 
 stood). Cleisthenes however probably 
 changed this mode of election into 
 choosing by lot, but left the right of 
 eligibility unchanged; and with this 
 the arrangement under which Aristides 
 held the office of archon, and the case 
 mentioned in Herodotus vi. 109, cor- 
 respond. Lastly, Aristides gave all 
 the Athenians the right of filling the 
 situation of archon by castiug lots, 
 without any distinction of property, a 
 right which the people had earned in 
 battle with their blood.] 
 
 '^^ I must here make an additional 
 remark upon the qualification to pub- 
 lic office arising from the valuation in 
 reference to Hermogenes. This writer 
 says, {rexv. pijrop. p. 35,) TrpeafievovTos 
 
 TOV TTevqTOS 6 TtKoVCTIOS ^X^pOS 03V elcTT)- 
 
 veyKS vopiov, rov e'lcrco TreVre Tci\dvTOiv 
 ovaiav Ke<Tr]p,€Vov p.rj TroXirevecrdai p,r)8e 
 "Keyeiv, from which he afterwards 
 draws farther inferences. See again 
 p. 36, and the passages of Marcellinus 
 quoted by Meursius F. A. iv. This 
 expression INIeursius has referred to 
 Athens, and converted into an histori- 
 cal fact : it is however evidently a case 
 supposed by Hermogenes, and even if 
 in inventing it, his mind was influ- 
 enced by some historical fact, we can 
 derive no benefit from it, since neither 
 the time nor place of this occurrence 
 can be assigned. 
 
 ''" See concerning tliis expresgion 
 Schneider ad Aristot. CEcon. 2, 5.
 
 CH. VI.] 
 
 PUBLIC REGISTERS, 
 
 511 
 
 little apprehension of low returns, for every one was glad to 
 appear wealthy, as Isocrates^*' tells us of the time of his boy- 
 hood, about the beginning of the Peloponnesian war: when on 
 the contrary he wrote his oration concerning the exchange 
 (Olymp. 106, S, B.C. 354), the appearance of riches led to great 
 losses; and although the concealment of property might be 
 attended with total ruin, many persons returned the smallest 
 amount possible. But the property of individuals being sub- 
 ject to reverses of fortune, the citizens were necessarily often 
 translated from one class to another; consequently a new valua- 
 tion was made in some states every year, and in larger nations 
 every two or four years'^*, and the translation from one class to 
 another (aj/acryi/raft?)'" took place. Again, if the whole wealth 
 of the nation varies, the rates of the classes, and the whole 
 division becomes ineffectual, more particularly if the quantity 
 of gold should be augmented, for which reason Aristotle recom- 
 mends the legislator to compare the amount of the whole valua- 
 tion (to ttXtjOos tov kolvov TtfjuTjfjLaTo^) with the rates of the 
 classes, and to rectify the latter according to it. Lastly, either 
 landed property alone, or sometimes only the productive land 
 (as was the case in the classes of Solon), or property of every 
 sort, was returned to be taxed, and according as the valuation 
 was made upon these several principles, either a register of 
 lands or a general register of property was formed. Plato in 
 the Laws^^"* proposes two registers; in the first place, a cata- 
 logue of all estates, and secondly, a separate list of every other 
 description of property, in order that all disjDutes on the sub- 
 ject might be easily decided, and be free from all obscurity. 
 
 Besides the register of lands Athens had a general register 
 of all property; the former was the more ancient, and cannot 
 have been introduced later than with the constitution of Solon. 
 Neither in Athens, however, nor in the ideal state of Plato was 
 the object of this register of lands the same as of the registers 
 
 85, sq. 
 
 '*' Isocrat. de Antidosi, p. 
 Orell. 
 
 >5^ Aristot. Polit. v. 8. 
 
 •'3 It was so called in the Athenian 
 symmoriee according to Snidas, see 
 
 Lex. Seg. p. 184, 31, Zonaras p. 186, 
 Harpocration, Suidas,and Zonaras (p. 
 205,) in V. avao-vvra^as. 
 ''* V. p. 741, c. p. 745 A.
 
 512 
 
 PUBLIC REGISTERS. 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 of mortgages in use in Germany; for it cannot be proved that 
 at Athens the debts upon landed property were entered in a 
 public book, but the creditor was ensured, if he required it, by 
 pillars or tablets {a-TrjXai, 6 pot) set up on the boundary of the 
 mortgaged estate. In no place but Chios do we hear of regis- 
 ters of debts^". There could have been no inducement to enter 
 the property of the state in the register of lands; on the con- 
 trary, the property of other corporations, particularly of the 
 demi, and at least of such temples as were only small corpora- 
 tions and had no connexion with the state, were necessarily 
 included in it; for the property of corporations was always tax- 
 able according to its proper scale (at least about the 114th or 
 115th Olympiad) ^^^ upon the imposition of extraordinary taxes. 
 The mines were also a part of the public property, which were 
 granted in perpetual leases; consequently these too could not 
 have been entered in the register of lands. 
 
 The formation as well as the custody of this register pro- 
 bably belonged at the time of Cleisthenes to the forty-eight 
 naucrari, to whom is ascribed the collection of the taxes 
 [el(T(f>opaiY^'' ', that is to say, it was the duty of these officers to 
 collect the taxes imposed according to the valuation, on those 
 rare occasions when in the ancient time of Athens it was neces- 
 sary to resort to this method of raising money. When they 
 were replaced by the demarchs, the latter made the registers of 
 the landed estates in each demus'^^ From a false reading in 
 the SchoHast to Aristophanes, by which the word debts has 
 been substituted in the place of lands, it might appear that the 
 demarchs entered the latter in the register; but nothing farther 
 
 >" Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. ii. 12. 
 
 ^^^ 'Atto TOiv \(iipi(i)v Toi) Ti^rjfiaTos, 
 Corp. Inscript. No. 103. Above, b. 
 iii. note A. [Also in another inscrip- 
 tion, containing a lease by an Attic 
 demus, in Olymp. 108, 4 (b.c.34o), edv 
 Tis (Icrcfiopa imep rov x,(opiov yiyvrjTai els 
 rfjv noXiu. Ibid. No. 93. — Transl.J 
 
 "' Ilesych. in v. vavKXapos. 
 
 '^^ Harpocrat. in v. hr]p.apxoi : ovtol 
 be Tus dnoypatpas enoLovvro rcov eKaarat 
 (1. ev eKacTTtp) bT)p.a> x^P'-^^ ' thence 
 
 Suidas, who reads tS>v Trpoaovroiv cAcao- 
 Toy drjfico ;^<a/3ta)i' : he added npodovTcov 
 because iv was likeTvdse wanting in the 
 manuscript which he used. The Scho- 
 liast to Aristoph. Nub. 37, has a false 
 reading : oi be br]p.apxoi. ovtol tus ano- 
 ypa<p6.5 enoiovvTO rcov ev eKacrrto Brjuco 
 Xpea}v : who must have transcribed it 
 from an indistinct MS. of some Lexi- 
 con, and probably from Harpocration, 
 whose words, with the exception of 
 this error, are the same.
 
 CH. VI.] PUBLIC REGISTERS. 513 
 
 is known from any other passage, of registers of debts being 
 kept in the demi; and even if, as is stated, the demarch as an 
 officer of police put the mortgagees in possession ^'% no fartlier 
 inference can be drawn from this circumstance. The demarch 
 had no concern with debts, except that he enforced the pay- 
 ment of the debts owing to the demus'^% and might have been 
 employed for the collection of monies which individuals owed 
 to the state^^'. 
 
 A.t a subsequent period the general register of property was 
 introduced, and on this the valuation in the year of Nausinicus 
 was founded; in which the concealment of property was prac- 
 tised to a great extent^^^ This census not only comprehended 
 lands and houses, but all unemployed and employed capital, 
 slaves, raw and manufactured materials, cattle, household furni- 
 ture, in short all money and money's worth were estimated, as 
 may be easily seen by comparing the property left by Demos- 
 thenes the father^^% with the valuation of the son's property. 
 It is evident that the resident aliens were also entered in this 
 register, although, with the exception of the proxeni and isoteles, 
 they were not included in any register of landed property; but 
 they were undoubtedly entered in a separate register, in the 
 same manner as when the symmoriee of the property taxes 
 were introduced, the resident aliens composed separate sym- 
 morise*: for they were taxed upon a different scale from the 
 citizens. 
 
 '5^ Ilarpocrat. Suid. Hesych. Schol. 
 Aristoph. Lex. Seg. p. 242. 
 "5° Book ii. ch. 3, iii. ch. 2. 
 '^^ It is to be observed also that the 
 
 elanpaTTei Kai dnoypdcperai avTOv rr^v 
 ovaiav Koi ivc^vpid^ei' Koi touto KoXel- 
 rai uTToypdcfieiv. In the mean time it 
 is well known that any other citizen 
 
 demarch had the duty of delivering in | was free to do the same, and the de- 
 an account of the property of public \ march probably liad only to perform 
 
 debtors with reference to the confisca- this duty if no other person took it 
 
 upon himself. 
 
 ^^■^ Out of many passages only corap. 
 
 tion. Etym. in v. brjfxapxos : 'ATre- 
 
 ypdcf)€TO rds ovaias iKdarca rrpos to. 
 
 Brjfxoaia 6(j)\T]ixaTa, couf. Lex. Seg. p. j Isfeus de Apollod. Hered. p. 187, de 
 
 237. Zonaras, p.494,whogoesuponthe Dicseog. Hered. p. 110, 111, .-Esch. c. 
 
 authority of Chrysippus. The Lex. Seg. , Timarch. p. 117. 
 
 ismoreexplicitp. 119,inv.a7roypa(^eii/: I '^^ Demosth c. Aphob. i. p. 81 G. 
 
 Tov fjLT] l3ovXn^€uov eKTLvetv to 6<p\T]p.a, \ Concerning slaves see Isocrat. Trapez. 
 
 6 6(f)€i\et, 8i7r\ovTai to c(p\r]fia, Knl 6 \ 25. Of cattle it is evident. 
 
 drjfxapxos crvv to7s iSovKevrais tovtov j * See below, note 239. 
 
 2 L
 
 514 PUBLIC REGISTERS. [bK. IV. 
 
 It deserves a particular consideration how the dowries were 
 entered in the register of property, and who it was that paid taxes 
 for them; they composed a considerable part of the moveable 
 property, even with poor people they amounted to 10, 20, and 
 25 minas, not unfrequently to 30 (which sum the state gave to 
 the daughters of Aristides), and even to 40, 50, 60, 80, 100, or 
 120 minas'^"*. The daughter of Hipponicus received 10 talents 
 at her marriage, and 10 others were promised her. Yet, 
 according to Demosthenes ^®% an Athenian seldom gave so much 
 as 5 talents, which sum, however, Pasion^s widow asserted that 
 she brought to Phormion. Dowries of 5 or 10 talents in 
 Lucian'®^ and the comic poets must be ascribed to the liberal 
 donations of comedy. If it is considered that generally the 
 husband was obliged to give security by a pledge for the dowry, 
 when it was made over to him'®^, and that the person who held 
 the security used to receive the income arising from it, it may 
 be thought that it was the kinsman who endow^ed the wife, and 
 not the husband, w^ho paid the tax for the dowry. But this 
 view of the case is untenable. The very reason why the hus- 
 band received the dowTy was that he might have the usufruct of 
 it; if it was not made over to him, he received the interest from 
 it*"; if then he gave a security for it, the interest of this secu- 
 rity he must have still retained, and therefore have paid the tax 
 for the dowry. This view is confirmed by the relation w^hich the 
 dowry bore to the property of the son. If the mother lived 
 after the death of the father in the same house with the son, 
 the law was that in case of the dyrlBoo-cs or exchange, the dowry 
 followed the property of the son'^^; consequently it belonged to 
 
 ^^* Isaeus de Ciron. Hered. p. 199, 
 de Hagn. Hered. p. 292, de Meneel. 
 Hered. p. 212, 213, ed. Orell. Epist. 
 Plat. xiii. p. 361 E, Orat. c. Neser. p. 
 1362, 9, Lys. Apol. pro Mantith. p. 
 IIH, Deniosth. c. Spud. p. 1029, 24, 
 Isaeus de Dicseog. Hered. p. 104, Lys. 
 c. Diogit. p. 896, 897, Demosth. c. 
 Aphob. i. p. 814 sqq. c. Onetor. i. ii. 
 passim, c. Boeot. de Dote, p. 1009, 28, 
 c. Aphob. de Falso Testim. p. 858, 25, 
 c. Boeot. de Dote, p. 1016, 23, c. Aphob. 
 
 i. p. 834, 13, ii. p. 840, 12 sqq. Con- 
 cerning Aristides' daughters see book 
 ii. ch. 18. 
 
 '" C. Stephan. p. 1110, 4, p. 1124^ 
 2,p. 1112, 19. 
 
 '^•^ Dial. J^Ieretr. 4. 
 
 '®' Harpocrat. in v. oTrort/xT^/xa, Lex. 
 Seg p. 201. 
 
 '*° Demosth. c. Onetor. i. p. 866, 4 
 
 '*'» Orat. c. Pliaenipp. p. 1047, 10— 
 16.
 
 CH. VI.] PUBLIC REGISTERS. 515 
 
 the taxable property of the son. In like manner in the esti- 
 mate of the property of Demosthenes, amounting to 15 talents, 
 according to which his valuation was fixed, the dowry of the 
 mother was included'^". 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 
 The Valuation in the Archonship of Nausinicus (b.c. 3/8). 
 
 After these observations upon the different registers of pro- 
 perty, we come to a new valuation made in Olymp. 100, 3, 
 during the archonship of Nausinicus (b.c. 378); concerning 
 which, although a point of the first importance in the Athenian 
 system of taxation, we have nothing but obscure and uncon- 
 nected accounts, like the legends of mythical history. Never- 
 theless, by a comparison of the scattered information now 
 extant, although there appear at first to be some contradictions 
 in the statements, it will nevertheless be found that the question 
 admits of historical precision. 
 
 At the beginning of the investigation I will set down a pas- 
 sage from the oration against Aphobus, in which Demosthenes, 
 in order to prove that his father had left him a considerable 
 property, makes use of the following words: "My guardians 
 returned me to the symmoria as contributing 500 drachmas for 
 every 25 minas, as much as Timotheus the son of Conon and 
 those who had the highest valuations contributed;" a declara- 
 tion which is several times repeated, but in rather a concise 
 manner, and expressed in less accurate words^^*. From this 
 
 ^7" See above, chap. 3. j rrjaas, ovk eVi fiiKpois rifirjixaaiv, dXX* 
 
 ^^^ C. Aphob. i. p. 815, 10, Els yap fVt TrjXiKovTois, acrre Kara ras rrevre 
 rrjv crvfifiopLav vTrep ip,ov avvcrd^avTO \ Kal (lkocti fivas nevTaKocrias elacfiepfiv. 
 Kara ras Tvevre koX € lkocti fivas TrevraKo- \ C Aphob. de Fals. Testim. p. 862, 7, 
 aias dpaxp-as elcrcfiepeiVy oaovnep Ti/id- j "Oti, nevTCKaibeKa TokdvTcov ovaias fxoi 
 Oeos 6 Kovccivos Koi ol ra fxeyiara KeKrr)- KUTaXeKpdeio-rjs tov p-eu oiKov ovk ip'icr- 
 
 pevoL Tiprjpara ^^((pepov- ii. p. 836, 25, 
 "Eti §€ Kal auTos "A^o/Sos pera ra>v av- 
 vcniTpoTTcou TTJ TToXfi TO nXrjOos T<OV 
 KaraXeKJidevrau xprjpdTcov epfjiaves iiroL- 
 
 doLXTCf oeKa 6 errj pera tcov GvvenLTpo- 
 TTOip diaxeipicras npos piv ttjv (rvppopiav 
 vnep naidos uutos ipov nevTe pvas avvt- 
 rd^ar* el(rcf)€peLU, ocrov Trep Tcpodcos 6 
 
 Tjcrev, Tjyfpova pe rrji avppopias Kama- Kdj/a>i/os <a\ ol to. peyiara KfKTrjpsvoi 
 
 2 L 2
 
 516 
 
 THE VALUATION IN THE 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 Statement it has been inferred that the guardians of Demos- 
 thenes returned as a property tax (elo-cfyopd) either the fifth part 
 of his property, or the fifth part of his yearly income'^^ The 
 former upon a superficial view might appear to be the meaning 
 of the passage; the latter is wholly devoid of all foundation, for 
 the orator speaks of the fifth part of the property, and not of 
 the income. The time moreover in which this tax may be 
 supposed to have fallen, has been fixed at about the 103rd 
 Olympiad, the orations against Aphobus having been spoken 
 in Olymp. 104, 1 (b.c. 364). But this is incorrect. Demos- 
 thenes speaks of the contribution to the symmoriee as having 
 been made by his guardians, at a time when his property still 
 amounted to 15 talents, which could only have been the case in 
 the beginning of the guardianship. If the return had taken 
 place later, they could not have rated it so high, since they 
 gradually either squandered away the property, or got fraudu- 
 lent possession of it. Moreover Demosthenes was for ten years 
 of his minority the leader of a symmoria^^% viz., of a symmoria 
 of the property taxes, and not of the trierarchy, for orphans did 
 not serve any trierarchy: and in the second oration against 
 Aphobus he expressly speaks of being leader of a symmoria of 
 the property taxes during his minority. Now Demosthenes^ 
 father died when his son was seven years old; the son was 
 born, according to the correct statement in the Lives of the 
 Ten Orators and in Photius, in Olymp. 98, 4 (b.c. 385), during 
 the archonship of Dexitheus, and not, as is supposed by others, 
 in Olymp. 99, 4 (b.c. 381) '^^ Consequently the son first 
 became an orphan, and first fell into the hands of guardians, in 
 Olymp. 100, j (b.c. 377)? at the same time also he became the 
 leader of a symmoria, and continued to be so for ten years. 
 This return made to the symmoriae coincides therefore exactly 
 with the period at which the valuation in the year of Nausinicus 
 had been just taken, and it is to this impost that the statement 
 of Demosthenes evidently refers. 
 
 TijjL-qiJLaTa €lat<p€pov' xpovov de ToaovTOV 
 ra -x^prjixaTa ravra €niTpo7r€V(rcis, vnep 
 a>p TT]XiKavTr)v avro? elcrcfinphv ■q^'iixxrev 
 cla(f>ep€iv, &c. 
 
 ''^ Herald, vi. 1, 7. 
 particularly in note SO. 
 '7^ Demosth. in INIid. p 
 '7^ See Wolf, p. G2 sq. 
 
 Wolf, p. 99, 
 05, 12.
 
 CH. VII.] ARCHONSHIP OF NAUSINICUS. 51? 
 
 But who can imagine that at that time, or indeed in any- 
 state, and at any time, a property tax of 20 per cent, was 
 levied? If such an event occurred frequently, the property of 
 the citizens must in a short time have either been entirely anni- 
 hilated, or reduced to a very small amount, as was actually the 
 case in Syracuse, during the reign of Dionysius, who in five 
 years nearly reduced the citizens to indigence, by means of 
 taxes' ^^ Without therefore stating those conclusions which 
 the reader himself will be able to deduce from what follows, I 
 only remark, that, according to Demosthenes, the Athenians 
 did not willingly pay large property taxes, and that an immense 
 sum would have been raised if the tax had been a fifth part 
 of the property; whereas that imposed in the year of Nausi- 
 nicus did not produce much more than 300 talents' ^^ 
 
 Demosthenes, in fact, returned to the symmoria a fifth part 
 of his whole property (etVe^epev etV rrjv avfjU/jLoplav), which he 
 inaccurately calls to contribute, or to pay taxes {elacpepetv) ; the 
 sum returned was not however his tax, but his taxable capital 
 (rifjLTjfjLa) : " for a property of 15 talents,'^ he says, " the taxable 
 capital or the valuation amounts to 3 talents: a tax of this 
 amount is what I ought justly to have paid;" i, e., whatever was 
 the proper per-centage of this sum'". The valuation {rifMrjfjLa) 
 is here accurately distinguished from the property, and just as 
 distinctly from the tax. For how many taxes did Demosthenes 
 pay? His guardians had, according to their own statement, 
 paid 18 minas in the ten years of their guardianship for extra- 
 ordinary taxes'^^: therefore the taxes of these years amounted 
 altogether, and not merely for one year, to the tenth part of the 
 valuation, or to the fiftieth part of the property. 
 
 '75 Aristot. Polit v. 11. 
 
 176 Demosth. c. Androt. p. 606, 27. 
 
 1^7 This is evidently the meaning of 
 the words in the first speech against 
 Aphobus, p. 815, 26. ArjXov fxev tolvvv 
 
 KoX €K TOVTOiV eazl TO TrXijOoS TTJS ovffias- 
 
 TrevreKaideKa raXavrcov yap rpia raKavra 
 TifiTjixa. TuvTi-jv rj^lovv el(T(f)ep€iv rrjv 
 elacfiopdv. It is to this that the useless 
 
 rrjs ovaias ela-cfyepofiepov •nap'' eKacrTov, 
 for example, in Photius, p. 433, ed. 
 Leips. 
 
 '78 C. Aphob. i. p. 825,7. EtV^opa? 
 S' elaeur]vox^vai \oyi^0VTai dvoivdeovaas 
 e'lKocTi fivaS' I may remark, by the 
 way, that in the accounts of the 
 guardians there is no mention of the 
 regular payment of a duty according 
 
 interpretation in the grammarians re- to the valuation (reXos) ; a strong proof 
 fers, that riprjpa was also called to €k i that no such thing existed at Athens.
 
 518 THE VALIATIOX IN THE [^K. IV. 
 
 From this simple explanation it is evident, that in the valu- 
 ation taken in the archonship of Nausinicus, the principle of 
 Solon's valuation was followed in three points, viz., in the regis- 
 tration of the property itself {ova la), the taxable part of it, or 
 the valuation (rifjurj/jLa), and, lastly, the tax fixed according to 
 the valuation {elacpopa in the limited sense). The estimate of 
 the property was obtained by a valuation of all moveables and 
 immoveables ; the valuation, or the taxable capital, was only a 
 certain part of this general census, and in the highest classes, 
 to which Timotheus and Demosthenes belonged, was the fifth 
 part; in the others, however, it was a smaller portion; for De- 
 mosthenes expressly says, that only those who had the highest 
 valuations were rated at 500 drachmas for each 25 minas. If, 
 for example, we reckon four classes, the valuation of the second 
 may perhaps have been one-sixth of the property, of the third 
 one-eighth, and of the fourth one-tenth, in order that the poor 
 might be taxed in a fair proportion. It should be also ob- 
 served, that those persons in the same class whose property was 
 different did not contribute an equally high valuation, but only 
 the same part of their property; in the first class it was 5 for 
 every 25 minas; thus the possessor of 15 talents contributed 3, 
 of 25 contributed 5, of 50 contributed 10; for the reason that 
 the estimate of the whole property of Demosthenes amounted 
 to 3 talents was, that for 25 minas 5 was in his class the rate of 
 the taxable capital. But of the taxable capital each person paid 
 the same part, whenever any tax was imposed; and how large a 
 part was to be taken couM be easily determined, as the sum 
 total of all the valuations was known, which in the archonship 
 of Nausinicus amounted to 5750 talents. 
 
 In order to make this clear, let us assume, for the sake of 
 example, four classes, and in the second one-sixth, in the third 
 one-eighth, in the fourth one-tenth, as the portion on which the 
 tax was imposed: farther, as the least property from which 
 taxes were paid, 25 minas ; so that the latter is the lowest 
 estimate of property in the last class ; as the lowest estimate in 
 the third class 2 talents, in the second class 6, in the first 12; 
 which are arbitrary assumptions^ except that, as we shall remark 
 below, 25 minas were probably taken as the lowest property
 
 CH. VII.] 
 
 ARCnONSHIP OF NAUSINICUS. 
 
 519 
 
 which was subject to taxation. If, then, a twentieth was to be 
 raised, the tax would have fallen in the manner shown by the 
 
 following table : — 
 
 Classes. Property. 
 
 Of which was 
 Taxable. 
 
 T„aMe Cap.ua. ^^T^J-' 
 
 i 500 talents 
 
 First of 12 ! 100 talents 
 
 talents and ' 50 talents 
 
 over ; 15 talents 
 
 12 talents 
 
 One fifth 
 One fifth 
 One fifth 
 One fifth 
 One fifth 
 
 100 talents 5 talents 
 
 20 talents 1 talent 
 
 10 talents 30 minas 
 
 3 talents ' 9 minas 
 
 2 tal. 24 min. 720 drachmas 
 
 Second of 6 
 talents and 
 over, under 
 12 talents 
 
 11 talents 
 10 talents 
 8 talents 
 7 talents 
 6 talents 
 
 One sixth I tal. 50 min. 550 drachmas 
 One sixth 1 tal. 40 min. 500 drachmas 
 One sixth 1 tal. 20 min. 400 drachmas 
 One sixth 1 tal. 10 min. 350 drachmas 
 One sixth 1 talent 300 drachmas 
 
 Third of 2 
 talents and 
 over, under 
 6 talents 
 
 5 talents One eighth ' 37 5 minas ^ 1874 drach. 
 4 talents One eighth 30 minas 1 50 drach. 
 3 talents One eighth 22i minas II24 drach. 
 2i talents One eighth 18| minas 93f drach. 
 2 talents One eighth 15 minas 75 drach. 
 
 Fourth of 
 25 minas 
 and over, 
 under 2 
 talents 
 
 1| talents ' One tenth 900 drachmas 45 drachmas 
 
 1 talent One tenth 600 drachmas : 30 drachmas 
 
 45 minas One tenth 450 drachmas 22^ drachmas 
 
 30 minas ' One tenth 300 drachmas 15 drachmas 
 
 25 minas One tenth j 250 drachmas , 12^ drachmas 
 
 An arrangement such as this cannot be considered as very 
 skilful for a state, in which from the beginning of the Pelopon- 
 nesian war many experiments might have been made as to the 
 collection of property taxes : the mismanagement of its finances 
 must not, however, be attributed to a want of political know- 
 ledge, but to the endeavours of the government to effect more 
 than it was able ; while the passions of individuals and of the 
 populace interrupted the most beneficial measures, and the 
 whole state was frequently blind to its real interest; at the 
 period, however, of this valuation, there was no want of good 
 intentions either in the Athenian state itself or among foreign 
 powers towards it.
 
 520 
 
 EXTRAORDINARY TAX IN 
 
 [bk, 
 
 IV. 
 
 Chapter VIIL 
 
 What proportion of the Property and the Valuation was levied 
 as an Extraordinary Tax, in the year of Nausinicus, 
 
 Since in the two valuations, concerning which some suffi- 
 ciently accurate accounts are extant, that of Solon in the 
 46th Olympiad, and that of the year of Nausinicus in the 
 100th Olympiad, a distinction, as has been already shown, was 
 made between taxable capital and property, we may infer that 
 this was a fixed principle at Athens, and that the rate of charge 
 w'as the only thing that varied. If in Olymp. 88, 1 (b.c. 428), 
 the total of the taxable capital of Attica was that which Euri- 
 pides assumed as the basis of his proposal for the levying of a 
 property tax, viz., 20,000 talents, the first property tax, as 
 Thucydides states, must have been a 100th (e/carocrr^), since it 
 produced 200 talents, in the same manner as that calculated by 
 Euripides to produce 500 talents was a fortieth {TeaaapaKoarrj). 
 In the Ecclesiazusee of Aristophanes^ '% w'hich was acted in 
 Olymp. 96, 4 (b.c. 393), a 500th {irevTaKoaiodTrj) is mentioned: 
 this was probably a smaU property tax levied at that time in 
 order to meet the public expenses, and its highest produce 
 could not have exceeded 40 talents. At that time, however, 
 the taxable capital, if it really amounted to so high a sum, came 
 much nearer to the whole property than in the archonship of 
 Nausinicus, since in that year it amounted only to 5750 talents. 
 Demosthenes^^", estimating the taxable capital in round num- 
 bers at 6000 talents, reckons, according to this new method of 
 taxation, the 100th at 60, and the 50th {TrevrfjKoaTr]) at 120 
 talents. " Shall I suppose,'^ he proceeds to say, ^^that you will 
 
 ''^ Vs. 999. Although this passage 
 is extremely obscure, the reading is 
 unquestionably correct : Ei fxrj rav 
 ifiSiv Ttjv TrevraKocrioaTijv KariOqKas rfj 
 TToXct, and twv eVcoi/, which Avas pro- 
 posed by Tyrwhitt, is highly absurd. 
 In order to obtain the meaning of these 
 words, something ai)pears to be want- 
 
 ing to us fi-om the Athenian law, upon 
 which the conclusion is founded which 
 Aristophanes supposes the young man 
 to draw. I Iiave intentionally omitted 
 to pay any regard to the inter])retation 
 of the scholiast, 
 
 "*" De Symmcn-. p. liio, lli.
 
 CH. VIII.] THE YEAR OF NAUSINICUS. 521 
 
 contribute a twelfth {ScoSeKarrj), which would produce 500 
 talents ? but a tax so high as that you would not endure." 
 From this passage it is plain beyond a doubt, that the Athe- 
 nians, at that time, never taxed themselves so high as a twelfth 
 part of the valuation, which, however, for the most wealthy 
 only came to If per cent., and for other persons far less. 
 
 Two property taxes are known, which can be calculated 
 with great accuracy from the valuation in the year of Nausi- 
 nicus. The one was imposed a year after Demosthenes' speech 
 upon the symmoriee, in which the taxable capital is stated at 
 6000 talents; and occurred when the Athenians, in Olymp. 
 106, 4 (b.c. 353), in the month Maimacterion, on account of 
 PhiUp's siege of the Hereeon Teichos, decreed to send out forty 
 ships, and to raise a property tax of 60 talents^^'. It was a 
 100th {eKaroarrj), which the orator states to have been charged 
 at that precise rate, that is, one-fifth per cent, of the property 
 of the most wealthy. The other is the tax in the archonship of 
 Nausinicus, which produced rather more than 300 talents ; this 
 must consequently have been a 20th [elKoarrjy^'^, It might, 
 indeed, be thought improbable that the 100th produced any 
 more than 574, or the 20th more than 287i talents, since the 
 valuation, according to Polybius, amounted exactly to 5750 
 talents ; but it must be remembered, that the resident aliens 
 also were taxed, who are not included in this valuation ; and 
 they not only made good what in the former case was wanting 
 to the 60, in the latter to the 300 talents, but were obliged to 
 contribute a large additional sum; with this addition, there- 
 fore, the whole taxable capital would doubtless have amounted 
 to 6000 talents. Demosthenes also unquestionably contributed 
 to the tax of a 20th, in the year of Nausinicus ; those 18 minas 
 
 ■'^^ Demosth. Olyntli. iii. p. 29, 20. the collection of taxes by a vitupera- 
 ^"^^ Demostli. c. Aiulrot. p. G17, 22, tive terra. If, however, any person 
 uses the word Se/careLicti' with reference sliould wisli to attribute to this word 
 to the payment of the taxes in the its literal sense, he should bear in 
 archonship of Nausinicus, and the same j mind, that the orator also says, bnfKas 
 word in the oration against Timocrates, irpaTTOvrcs ras elactiopas, and that a 
 p. 751], 4. This, however, is a general j tax of a 20th twice collected makes a 
 expression, when tiie object is to denote 10th.
 
 522 EXTRAORDINARY TAX IX [bK. IV. 
 
 which the guardians charged in their account were however, as 
 he himself says, for several taxes; to that tax he could not have 
 contributed more than 9 minas, which was the 20th part of his 
 taxable capital ; the other 9 were either for another tax of a 
 20thj or two of a 40th, or for two 50ths and one 100th. These 
 property taxes were, therefore, by no means excessive ; in ten 
 years Demosthenes only paid the 10th part of his taxable 
 capital, or the 50th part of his property, and indeed at the first 
 tax in the archonship of Nausinicus only half this rate, or 1 per 
 cent. ; his property, however, even if we deduct a 6th part as 
 paying no interest, must have returned a premium of 10 per 
 cent. : 1 per cent, of his property is consequently the 10th part 
 of his income. Or, in order to place the subject in a more 
 striking light, while in ten years he only paid 2 per cent, from 
 his whole property, the same brought in, if it was tolerably 
 managed, 100 per cent. 
 
 This clearly shows the absurdity of the assertions respecting 
 the exorbitant taxes of the Athenian citizens, more particularly 
 if we take into consideration the low rates of the custom duties, 
 and the cheapness of the chief necessaries of life, by which 
 they were enabled to live upon very small means. If notwith- 
 standing this there was a great disinclination to pay property 
 taxes, as may be plainly seen from the Olynthiacs and the 
 oration concerning the Chersonese, the fact cannot cause any 
 astonishment, as no one wilhngly taxes himself; and as to the 
 decrease of the national wealth, the causes originated in other 
 circumstances, the consideration of which does not belong to 
 this place. 
 
 It is, indeed, true that we find instances of large property 
 taxes, as, for instance, one mentioned in Lysias of 30, and 
 another of 40 minas; but the great expenses of the payer prove 
 the large amount of his property^ ^^; in proportion to which the 
 tax may have been very moderate, particularly since it only 
 occurred twice. Aristophanes, as is mentioned in the same 
 orator, likewise paid 40 minas as his share of the property tax, 
 although this was not for himself alone, but for his father also ; 
 
 '^^ See book iii. ch, 22.
 
 CH. VIII.] 
 
 THE YEAR OF NAUSINICUS. 
 
 523 
 
 nor upon one occasion^ but for several taxes, and in times of 
 the greatest exertions, during the four or five years after the 
 battle of Cnidos (Olymp. 96, 2, B.C. 395); and that Aristo- 
 phanes (Lysias may conceal it as he will) must have been very 
 wealthy, is proved by the choregias, which he served for his 
 father and himself; the three years^ trierarchy, upon which he 
 expended 80 minas ; by his having given 5 talents for land, 
 and being possessed of much furniture ; and also by his having, 
 even before the times of the Anarchy, subscribed 100 minas to 
 the expedition against Sicily, and subsequently 30,000 drachmas 
 to the auxiliary fleet for the Cyprians and Euagoras, which sum 
 was, without doubt, paid by Euagoras in the island of Cyprus, 
 where his father was settled'^*. 
 
 At the same time, I will not deny that many persons volun- 
 tarily contributed more than their means allowed, and that 
 many were oppressed by too high valuations, while others con- 
 cealed their property ; as, for instance, Dicseogenes, mentioned 
 in Iseeus, who from an income of 80 minas contributed nothing 
 to many property taxes, as he concealed his property, except 
 that he once voluntarily gave 3 minas'"; nor, lastly, that a 
 frequent repetition of these taxes at short intervals of time, 
 particularly when, as was the case after the Anarchy, the 
 channels of industry were blocked up, was a great national 
 calamity^ ^^ : from which fact the complaints as to the oppres- 
 sion of the property taxes are sufficiently explained. 
 
 Chapter IX^ 
 
 Symmoria of the Property Taxes after the Archonship of 
 Natbsinicus. The Advance of Property Taxes, and other 
 Regulations relating to the Payment of them. 
 
 In the year of Nausinicus, the symmoriee (classes or compa- 
 nies'^') were introduced with reference to the property taxes. 
 
 '^* Lysias pro Aristoph. bonis. 
 642 sqq. cf. p. 633 sqq. and p. 637- 
 
 '^^^ Isaeus de Dicaeog. Hered, 
 109—111. 
 
 pp. 
 
 '"^^ Cf. Lys. c. Ergocl. pp. 818, 819. 
 
 '^7 See Heraldus vi. 2, 4, concerning 
 the name, which also is frequently ap- 
 plied to other sorts of companies.
 
 524 STMMORIiE OF [bK. IV. 
 
 These are what Harpocration'"' means when he quotes from 
 Philochorus the institution of the symmorice in the archonship 
 of Nausinicus, since the symmorise of the trierarchy were not 
 introduced till afterwards; and Demosthenes became imme- 
 diately after his seventh year in Olymp. 100, f (b.c. 377), the 
 leader of a symmoria'^': at that time, therefore, they had been 
 already estabhshed. After they had been once introduced, they 
 continued uninterruptedly until the 108th Olympiad. The fact 
 of Demosthenes having been for ten years a leader in the sym- 
 morise of the property taxes, proves their existence up to 
 Olymp. 103, -h (b.c. 367): they were, however, still in existence 
 in Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353), which is the date of the speech 
 against Meidias, since Demosthenes says of this person, that 
 '^ up to the day on which he was speaking he had never been 
 the leader of a symmoria'^'." Whether they were still in 
 existence in Olymp. 107, 4 (b.c. 349), has been questioned '^^, 
 because Demosthenes, in the second Olynthiac'^^ says to the 
 Athenians, that '' formerly they paid taxes by symmorise, but 
 now they administered the state by symmorise ;'' these words, 
 however, distinctly prove their existence at that time. For an 
 institution, like the symmorise, might very easily obtain a 
 powerful influence upon the public administration, as the dif- 
 ferent classes of property, and above all, the divisions of people 
 created by them, would produce political parties, and parties 
 could only retain their activity so long as the division existed. 
 Since then, as Demosthenes ironically says, the state was 
 governed by symmorise, the symmorise must have been estab- 
 lished by law. The custom of paying taxes by symmorise they 
 had disused ; for the obvious reason, that no one will pay taxes 
 if he has any means of avoiding them. The object of Demos- 
 thenes evidently is, as the whole oration proves, to raise a tax ; 
 
 '"^ In V. (Tv^iJLopia, and thence Pho- | Deinostli. c. Mid. p. 505, 19. 
 
 tins, Suidas, Scliol. Deraosth. vol. ii. i '^' Wolf, p. xcviii. note. 
 
 p. 55, Ileiske and ScaligcrinliisoXv/ATT. | '°- P. 20, 21, irporepov fxeu yap, co 
 
 dvayp. I civdes ^Adrjvciioi, (laecfiepere Kara avp- 
 
 '^^ See above, book iv. cli. 7. p.opias, vvv\ 6e 7ro\iT€V€a6e Kara ovp.- 
 
 ^^^ MftSias Se TTcUy; ovdtnai Koi p-opias. And thence in the oration 
 
 rrjpepov avppvpuis rjyenojv yeyovcv, ttc/ji a wrale cos, p. 172, 1.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 THE PROPERTY TAXES. 
 
 52: 
 
 but, seeing the disinclination of his hearers, he says to them 
 ironically, that the institution of the symmoriae had lost all its 
 meaning, and instead of taxes being raised according to it, that 
 they only used it for political purposes. If the oration against 
 Bceotus Trepl rov ovo/xaroq belongs to the first year of the 108th 
 Olympiad (b.c. 348), as has been supposed, we should have a 
 proof that at that time the symmoriae of the property taxes 
 were still in existence, since they are there mentioned' ^^ in 
 opposition to the trierarchy. The date of this speech may, 
 however, be placed with much greater probability in Olymp. 
 107, 1 (b.c. 352)'^^: yet I entertain no doubt that this consti- 
 tution of taxes was still in existence at the later period. 
 
 It should be observed, that Petit, and those who follow 
 him, have not recognised any connexion between the sym- 
 
 =»'' P. 997, 1. 
 
 '^^ Corsini F. A. t. iv. p. 30, and 
 Wolf, p. cix. sq. note, suppose tliis 
 speech to belong to Olymp. 108, 1, 
 after Dionysius : but preponderating 
 reasons compel me to dissent from this 
 opinion. Dionysius places the birth 
 of Dinarchus about the archonship of 
 Nicopheraus, in Olymp. 104, 4, and 
 states that at the time of the oration 
 against BcEotus rrepl ovonaTos, Dinar- 
 chus was thirteen years old, as this 
 oration belongs to the archonship of 
 QovfiT]bos or QeofxvTjTos ; the latter 
 because in the oration nepl ovofiaros the 
 expedition of the Athenians against 
 Pylae is mentioned as liaving lately 
 taken place. No such fact, however, 
 is mentioned in this oration : Diony- 
 sius clearly meant the expedition 
 against Tamynre, p. 999, and Diony- 
 sius should evidently be corrected from 
 this passage, Trjs els Tajxvvas i^obov 
 yeyevTjpevrjs, and the hiatus rj 8'' els . . . 
 ^Adr]vaioiv e^odos should be supplied 
 with Tajivvas and not with UvXas. 
 The probability is, tliat there was also 
 an hiatus formerly in the former woi'ds 
 TTjs els . ... e^odov yeyevrjfJLevrjS, the 
 copyist being unable to read, in either j 
 
 place, the name Tafivvas, of which lie 
 was ignorant. Some corrector then 
 inserted IlvXas in the former place, 
 who Iiad some vague notion of the 
 well-known expedition against Pylso. 
 Now Dionysius was only acquainted 
 with the expedition and the battle of 
 Tamynge from the oration against 
 INEeidias, which speech he falsely attri- 
 butes to OljTiip. 107, 4, allowing him- 
 self to be misled by the Olynthian ex- 
 pedition there mentioned ; and from 
 that he places the birth of Demos- 
 thenes four years too late. For the 
 same reason he also places the battle 
 of Tamynge four years too late ; since 
 it probably was fought in Olymp. 106, 
 4 (comp. below chap. 13). That the 
 date he assigns is 108, 1, whereas 
 agreeably to his calculation it should 
 have been Olymp. 107, 4, is in fact no 
 objection, as two successive civil years 
 are always confounded from their being 
 included in the same natural year, 
 reckoned from spring to spring. Con- 
 sequently, on account of the Euboean 
 expedition, and the battle of TamjTise, 
 the oration against Eceotus Trept 6v6- 
 fxaros must be placed four years earlier, 
 viz., about Olymp. I07, 1.
 
 526 SYMMORKE OF [bK. IV. 
 
 morise and the property taxes. Wolf has the merit of having 
 remarked after Heraldus the introduction of the symmoriae, 
 and of having distinguished between the passages which treat of 
 the symmorise of the property taxes, and the symmoriae of the 
 trierarchy. But after we have examined all the statements 
 concerning the property taxes and the valuation, and although 
 the solution will appear to possess sufficient clearness and sim- 
 plicity, the chief question as to the mode in which the sym- 
 morise of the property taxes were arranged, will not be answered 
 in a manner at all satisfactory. 
 
 The only detailed account of their constitution occurs in 
 the ignorant interpreter of Demosthenes^*^, whom we usually 
 call Ulpian, in a passage upon the second Olynthiac, wherein 
 we may follow Wolf in separating the first from the second 
 part, as being more ancient. " Each of the ten tribes,^^ he 
 says, "was obliged to specify 120 of its own members who 
 were the most wealthy. These 120 then divided themselves 
 into two parts, so that there were 60 whose property was very 
 large, and the other 60 less rich. They did this in order that 
 if a war should suddenly break out, and the less wealthy should 
 not happen to have any money at their disposal, those who 
 were more rich might advance the taxes for them, and be after- 
 wards repaid at the convenience of the others. This body of 
 60 was called a symmoria/^ In the second part, which is the 
 work of a different hand, it is stated, that " since each of the 
 ten tribes specified 120, the whole number of liturgi (as they 
 are here called) was 1200: that these were distributed into two 
 divisions, each of 600 persons, or ten symmoriee ; that these 
 two great divisions were again sub-divided into two smaller, 
 each of which was composed of 300 persons of five symmoriae. 
 One of these bodies of 300 was made up of the most wealthy, 
 who paid the taxes either before the others or for them {wpoei- 
 aicpepov rcov dWcov), the other 300 being in all things subject 
 to them.^^ So far the account is, in some measure, intelligible: 
 that which is further added is both absurd and foreign to our 
 purpose. 
 
 "^ P. :«, ed. Hieron. Wolf. See F. A. Wolf, p. xcv.
 
 CH. IX.] 
 
 THE PROPERTY TAXES. 
 
 527 
 
 According to this, then, it appears that two classes of 300, 
 under similar arrangements, were instituted, the members of 
 which were of nearly equal property, and advanced money for 
 the payment of taxes for two others equally poorer. There is, 
 however, no inteUigible reason why the 600 most wealthy were 
 to be divided into two equal portions, if in all other respects 
 they were similarly constituted ; it is far more probable that 
 the first 300 were a higher class ; therefore to pay taxes among 
 the 300, means the same as to pay taxes among those who 
 contributed the largest amowif^^. The only passage from which 
 it might be inferred that there existed two classes of 300 
 persons similarly constituted, is that already quoted from the 
 second Olynthiac^^^ (and it is from this that Ulpian has princi- 
 pally formed his view of the subject, and drawm many other 
 erroneous conclusions): "Now you administer the state by 
 symmoriee, an orator is the leader of both, and under him a 
 general, and the 300, who are always ready to clamour, while 
 the rest of you are assigned, some to one and some to the 
 other.^^ I confess that I do not entirely understand this 
 passage, but I can only explain it by supposing that two classes 
 of different degrees of wealth were the highest, since the 
 immediate effect of a different scale of property w^ould be to 
 create a spirit of party between the classes ; while the contest 
 which in ancient days always existed between the superior and 
 inferior, the rich and the poor, w^ould necessarily be combined 
 with it, although in a less degree. Upon this point, however, 
 we need give ourselves no trouble; but that 1200 was the 
 entire sum of those who paid taxes is wholly incredible, and 
 can by no means be assumed upon the testimony of such a 
 writer as Ulpian. 
 
 The passages of the ancient writers and of the grammarians 
 bearing on this subject are extremely indefinite; in several of 
 them we do not even know whether they refer to the Twelve 
 
 '*® Isaeus de Philoctem. Hered. p. 
 154, Orat. c. Plisenipp. p. 1046, 20, p. 
 1039, 17. The account given in Lex. 
 Seg. p. 306, is too vague to be of any 
 service. [That the 300 were the most 
 
 wealthy appears from Demosth. de 
 Corona, p. 285, 17. See below, note 
 394.— Transl.] 
 
 '^'' P. 26, and thence in the speech 
 TTfpi a-vvTa^eois with some alterations.
 
 528 SYMMORI^E OF [bK. IV. 
 
 Hundred of the property taxes, or of the trierarchy'''". The 
 Thousand, whom Harpocration quotes from Lysias and Tsceus, 
 and considers as identical with the Twelve Hundred, can 
 neither be referred to the symmoriee of the property taxes after 
 the year of Nausinicus, nor to the symmorioe of the trierarchy'^% 
 since Lysias died in Olymp. 100, f (b.c. 378*)"''''. Philochorus 
 treated of the symmorise in the archonship of Nausinicus, in 
 the fifth book of the Atthis'"^, but of the Twelve Hundred in 
 the sixth book*"*: they were therefore wholly distinct, so that 
 he rather appears to have mentioned the latter in connexion 
 with the trierarchy according to symmoriee which was subse- 
 quently introduced. Isocrates*"^^ however calls those who paid 
 taxes and performed liturgies '^ the Twelve Hundred '^' where 
 from the context all liturgies, and particularly the trierarchy, 
 may be understood; so that twelve hundred must have borne 
 all the property taxes and all liturgies, including the trierarchy. 
 But this passage again proves nothing, as it is perfectly fair 
 to suppose that an orator might express himself in such terms 
 in speaking of an exclusive class like the rich, who paid the 
 largest portion of taxes, and to whom the state on every occa- 
 sion first looked for assistance. And although similar state- 
 ments are highly embarrassing to the writer who endeavours to 
 reconcile all contradictory statements, yet the reasons for con- 
 sidering that all the inhabitants of the state not included in the 
 Twelve Hundred, whose property was at all considerable, were 
 subject to taxation, are so preponderating, that it is impossible 
 to refuse our assent to them. If we supposed that only twelve 
 hundred rich persons paid the property taxes, the result would 
 
 '®^ As e. g. of Harpocration in v. 
 avfxnopia (although in this passage the 
 symmoria? of Nausinicus are the sym- 
 nioiiaj of the property taxes) and in v. 
 ;(tX<ot dLaKc'xTioL. 
 
 ' 89 The latter is the opinion of Wolf, 
 
 ^""^ Ilarpoci-at. in v. ;^iXtot diuKoaioi. 
 
 =^"3 De Antidosi p. Hi), ed Orell. Els 
 derovs diaKoaiovs /cat xiXiovs rovs ela- 
 (pepovras k(u \(LT(wpyovvTas ov fiovop 
 avTuu 7rape)(€is, uXXa kuI tov vioV Tp\s 
 fiev ^^q TeTpirjp:ipx']KCiT€, ras S' aXXas 
 
 p. ex. note. XeiTovpyuis noXyrfXearfpov XeXeiTovp 
 
 20' Taylor, Vit. Lys. p. 150, vol. vi. 
 Reiske. 
 
 yrjKare Koi KaXXiov cov ol vofxoi irpocr- 
 TUTTovo-Lv. Similarly Harpocration in 
 
 ^*'' Harpocration, and thence Phot. v. ;^iX£Oi kcu SiaKoaioi : oi kgI eXeirovp- 
 Suid. and Etymol. in v. avpp.npia. yovv.
 
 CH. IX.] THE PROPERTY TAXES. 529 
 
 be in the highest degree improbable. In the oration against 
 Leptines, wliich was delivered in Olymp. 106, 2 (b.c. 355), 
 when the symmorice of the property taxes were in existence, 
 the rich both served the trierarchy and paid property taxes^""* 
 Thus, if there were only twelve hundred who contributed to the 
 property taxes, none but the trierarchs, as they were twelve 
 hundred in number, would have paid this impost ; which is evi- 
 dently absurd. Demosthenes says himself that those also paid 
 taxes who were too poor for the trierarchy. And how could it 
 have happened that no more than twelv^e hundred possessed a 
 sufficient amount of property to enable them to pay taxes, 
 since in the 94th Olympiad there were only five thousand citi- 
 zens not possessed of some landed property, and so late as in 
 Olymp. 114, 2 (b.c. 323), nine thousand citizens had more than 
 2000 drachmas^'''? And moreover how liberal would the 
 assembly have been with property taxes, if all the burden fell 
 upon twelve hundred! Lastly, as has been proved, the pro- 
 perty tax was a fixed part of the total valuation after the year 
 of Nausinicus, and it is frequently considered as such by De- 
 mosthenes, in the oration concerning the symmoriai''"^; but at 
 that time (Olymp. 106, 3, b.c. 354), the symmoriae of the pro- 
 perty taxes were in existence. The total valuation of 5750 or 
 6000 talents was not the property of only twelve hundred citi- 
 zens, but the valuation of the whole country {Ttfjbrjfjua rrjs 'xoipas), 
 according to the statements of Demosthenes and Polybius; 
 although Ulpian^*^^ infers from the obscure and difficult expo- 
 sition of Demosthenes in the speech concerning the symmoriae, 
 that it was only the valuation of the twelve hundred trierarchs. 
 It might indeed be easily proved by calculation, that twelve 
 hundred could not be the possessors of the whole valuation, if 
 an assumption which has already involved the supporters in 
 such evident contradictions needed farther refutation. Demos- 
 
 ^"^ See above cliap. 1. \ will return again to this subject in tlit 
 
 205 See chap. 3. 
 
 ^"•^ See chapters 4, 7, and 8. 
 
 207 p. 141. ,-,p 8e oixTiav ttjv twu 
 Xi^LOiv Koi 8iaKO(Ti(ov rpLr^pdpxoiv reri- 
 p.r)(T6ai (prjfTi raXavTCOv e^aKi(7;(iXt'coi'. I 
 
 twelfth chapter, when speaking of the 
 trierarcliy. Budsons indeed ut sup. p. 
 539, considei-s the 6000 talents as the 
 whole valuation, and in p. 540 sqq. as 
 the valuation of the Twelve Hundred. 
 
 2 M
 
 530 SYMMORIiE OF [bK. IV. 
 
 thenes was in the highest class, to which those who had the 
 largest valuations belonged; his valuation however only- 
 amounted to 3 talents. Assuming now that there were four 
 classes, which together made up tw^elve hundred persons, and 
 that each class contained about three hundred taxable mem- 
 bers; that moreover the valuation of the highest class was upon 
 an average greater than that of Demosthenes, for example, 5 
 talents (which supposes a property of 50 talents for each per- 
 son, and therefore is more likely to be too high than too low), 
 the total valuation of the first three hundred only amounted to 
 1500 talents. Now evidently the three other classes could not 
 have had three times 1 500 talents, because not only was their 
 property less, but the valuation was of a smaller part of that 
 property^^^. Let any person reckon as he pleases, let him 
 assume a greater or less number of classes, he never can obtain 
 6000 talents for twelve hundred men, if in the highest class 
 there were persons whose valuation only came to 3 talents, 
 unless indeed assumptions altogether groundless are admitted. 
 
 The calculation of Budaeus is wholly unfounded^'^. He 
 considers the Twelve Hundred alone as the superior class to 
 which Demosthenes belonged, and assumes that others had 
 higher valuations, for example, four hundred upon an average 
 3 talents, another four hundred 4 talents, and another four 
 hundred 8 talents, which altogether gives 6000 talents. But if 
 twelve hundred individuals were the sole owners of the whole 
 taxable property, the classes of valuation must have referred to 
 these alone. If the class of Demosthenes was that which had 
 the highest valuations, there must have been inferior classes ; 
 and in fact if twelve hundred possessed the whole valuation, 
 the lower classes must have been classes of the twelve hundred; 
 thus the hypothesis of the learned writer falls to the ground. 
 
 It is therefore far more probable that many others besides 
 the Twelve Hundred paid taxes, who, although their property 
 was less considerable, were assessed in the total valuation; and 
 this supposition receives considerable support from a fact men- 
 tioned in an oration of Demosthenes. Androtion was employed 
 
 2«« Book iv. cli. 7. •'■' Ut sup. p. 542.
 
 CII. IX.] THE PROPERTY TAXES. 531 
 
 to collect some outstanding taxes which belonged to the impost 
 laid on in the archonship of Nausinicus, 7 out of 14 talents; 
 they were however small sums, not one amounting to a mina, 
 as Demosthenes says, but a little more than 70 drachmas from 
 one person, and from another 34^ '\ That these were the 
 arrears of payments which had been made by instalments is 
 very improbable; we are nowhere informed that the payments 
 were ever made in this manner; nor is it indeed credible, since 
 the necessities of the state required prompt payment. We 
 should not therefore be justified in assuming that such a liberty 
 was granted by the state; and even if it did exist, what rich 
 man would have remained 34 drachmas in debt? It follows 
 therefore that these were taxes due from persons of small for- 
 tune, who, from their inability to pay them, were forced to sub- 
 mit to be insultingly treated by Androtion, and to be unjustly 
 thrown into prison; and since Androtion collected 7 talents, 
 and as no one paid a whole mina, he must have collected taxes 
 from at least four or five hundred persons. Now if we reckon 
 that the other 7 talents were in like manner chiefly made up of 
 small sums (which is the only probable supposition), it gives 
 about twelve hundred people whose taxes were in arrear; these 
 owever cannot have been the twelve hundred wealthy per 
 sons, but citizens of a lower valuation, who paid even such 
 small sums as these with difficulty. In addition to this the 
 lands of corporations were subject to the property taxes, as an 
 inscription of the 114th or 115th Olympiad shows^^^: the cor- 
 porations however cannot weU have been among the Twelve 
 Hundred. Or shall we assume that the symmoriee had been at 
 this period for the second time abolished? For that however 
 we should be compelled first to assume, contrary to all proba- 
 bility, that the property of the corporations had not been before 
 subject to taxation. 
 
 From the whole of this argument it follows that a number of 
 persons with small fortunes or valuations were distributed into 
 
 2'" Demosth. c. Androt. p. 606 sq. ! other respects nearly the same account 
 particularly p. 611, 21. In the speech is given in both places, 
 against Timocrates, p. 751, 4, only Si '^'' See above note 156. 
 talents are mentioned, although in 1 
 
 2 M 2
 
 532 
 
 SYMMORI.^ OF 
 
 [BK. 
 
 v. 
 
 symmorise, and in such a manner that equal parts of the valua- 
 tion were contained in them (in the same way that Demosthenes 
 proposed to distribute the valuation with regard to the trie- 
 rarchy)*'% and that the Twelve Hundred composed the first 
 class. There were according to Ulpian twenty symmorise, and 
 of these each one must have made up 300 talents, each could 
 be again subdivided into a fifth, and each fifth into a third, so 
 as to make three hundred, in the same manner that Demos- 
 thenes makes one hundred divisions. The three hundred most 
 wealthy can only have been the presidents of these divisions; 
 next to these would come three hundred, whose wealth entitled 
 them to the second rank; and after these two other divisions of 
 three hundred classed in like manner according to the value of 
 their property; and these twelve hundred together composed a 
 body that managed the affairs of the symmoriae, which duty 
 however fell chiefly upon the first three hundred. The mem- 
 bers of less property who were assigned to these, were not 
 taken into consideration, as the more wealthy were always com- 
 pelled to bear the chief part of the burden, and to manage the 
 business of the whole body. Thus at least the constitution of 
 the symmorice assumes an intelligible form, and the statements 
 of the ancients can be in some measure reconciled. If however 
 any other person can explain the subject in a more satisfactory 
 manner, to no one would it be more acceptable than to myself. 
 That the Three Hundred w^ere, in a certain sense, managers 
 of the symmoria3 there can be no doubt; but whether those 
 who are called the leaders of the symmoriae {rjyefiovef: avfi/juo- 
 pii/ivf^^ are the same, or whether they were only included in 
 them, is a point which I shall leave undetermined. Whichever 
 we suppose to have been the case, they must have been the 
 most wealthy, in the same way that in the trierarchy the second 
 and the third classes are opposed to the leaders^' ^ The sym- 
 moriarchs*'* were either the same with the leaders, or with the 
 
 212 See chap. 13. 
 
 ^'^ Concerning whom see book iv. 
 ch. 7, and Ilarpocrat. Suid. in v. 
 T)y€fxaiP avfiixoplas, although in the 
 latter place the leaders of the symmo- 
 
 risD connected with the trierarchy are 
 meant. 
 
 ="* Demosth. de Corona, p. 260, 20. 
 
 215 Hyperides ap. Poll. iii. 53. Ile- 
 raldus (vi. 2, 8) understands the sym-
 
 CH. IX.] THE PROPERTY TAXES. 533 
 
 superintendents of the symmorise {iirt^eKrjraX tmv (rvfi/MopLcov), 
 who occur in connexion with the trierarchy, and without doubt 
 they also belonged to the symmorise of the property taxes. Of 
 the manner in which these persons conducted the affairs of the 
 symmoriee we are entirely ignorant: it is however natural to 
 suppose that they presided over the meetings and proceedings 
 of the symmorites. It is certain that they kept the diagramma 
 of their symmoriae, which was a register of the properties of the 
 members, and of the amount which each one was respectively 
 required to pay, in the symmoriae of the property taxes as well as 
 in those of the trierarchy: but whether the persons who kept this 
 register (Bcaypacj^el^, iiri'y packets) were again different, or were a 
 committee of the superintendents of the symmorise, is unknown. 
 If the speech of Hyperides against Polyeuctus concerning the 
 diagramma, or that of Lysias concerning the property taxes, 
 which however is anterior to the institution of the symmoriae, 
 had come down to our days, we should be better informed 
 with regard to the valuation and all the subjects relating 
 to it^^^ 
 
 The chief persons were moreover compelled to pay the taxes 
 in advance ['jrpoei(T<f)opa), which obligation Ulpian ascribes to 
 his two bodies of three hundred under similar arrangements : 
 this however may be with more probability understood of the 
 first three hundred'''^: in the same manner as in modern times 
 forced loans have been taken from the rich, with which this 
 advance of taxes may be aptly compared, although the differ- 
 ences of the two are manifest. The advance of taxes was 
 always claimed; in the archonship of Nausinicus the duties 
 were collected by the state itself, as is proved by the fact 
 of Androtion^s gathering the taxes that were still unpaid; 
 whereas in cases where the taxes were to be paid in advance. 
 
 moriarcli to be the person who contri- Harpocrat. in v. eViypa^fiy, Zonaras 
 
 buted the most, for Avhich there is not in vv. diuypafiixa and eiriypacpels. 
 sufficient foundation. | ^'^ Orat. c. Phsenipp. p. 14G, 20 sq. 
 
 2"5 Harpocrat. in v.Staypa/i/Ma, where This Demosthenes Trepi o-u/x/xoptoij/, p. 
 
 observe the words Trpo? rrjv Tiixrjaiv \8o,\-i,ca\h pepos tcov ovroiv vnep iav- 
 
 rrjs ova-las, and thence Suidas in vv. tov nai toov Xolttcov npoeiaeveyKelv. The 
 
 8idypap.p,a, Sia-ypa/i/xara, diaypacfievs, aX\r}\eyyvov in the Byzantine empire 
 
 diaypa(t)Tj, also Lex. Seg. pp. 236, 241, was of the same nature.
 
 534 SYMMORf.E OF [liK. IV. 
 
 the payer had afterwards to recover the money which he had 
 advanced" ^ For the imposition of a tax to be paid in advance, 
 a decree of the people was necessary=*'% and sometimes even the 
 persons were appointed by the senate, who were to advance the 
 taxes for their fellow demotse, as well as for all others who pos- 
 sessed landed property in the demus {ol iyKeKTrj/jbevoi), The 
 client of Lysias in his oration against Polycles had landed pro- 
 perty in three demi, and w^as rated for all three to the advance 
 of taxes, although, as he was trierarch, he was under no obliga- 
 tion to pay them. 
 
 It should be observed that the relation with regard to this 
 point which existed between the demi and the symmoriae cannot 
 be accurately explained, nor is it of any importance for our 
 inquiries; but so much is clear from this example, that the 
 landed property was taxed according to the demi, a fact which 
 is not irreconcileable with the other regulations respecting 
 property taxes. In the same way in Potidsea the owners of 
 more than one estate paid taxes for each respectively to the 
 demus in which the land lay, and not collectively for all to the 
 demus in which he was himself entered; as this was the only 
 method of determining with certainty whether the less wealthy 
 had been justly taxed"^*'. It is manifest that there was a right 
 of action for recovering the money which had been advanced*'' ^ 
 The whole property was liable for the payment of taxes, the 
 state having the power of confiscating it in case of failure"*. 
 
 218 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1209, 4. 
 
 2'9 Ibid. p. 1208,25. 
 
 ^20 Pseud-Aristot. (Ecoii. 2, 5, and 
 there Schneider. 
 
 ^^' This is the meaning of Demosth. 
 c. Pantsonet. p. 877) 19, ai/ Trpoetcr^opai/ 
 IXT] KOjjLL^rjTaL, if a person was not repaid 
 the money wliich he had advanced. 
 
 22^2 Demosth. c. Androt. p. 609, 23, 
 and c. Tiraocrat. p. 752. To this Pho- 
 tius and Suidas in v. ttwXtjttjs also re- 
 fer; xmeKeiVTO Se roTp TrcoXrjTois Kul 
 
 in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 354, refers 
 to an elacfiopd. The inscription be- 
 longs to the time of the Romans, since 
 dpyvpoTajxiai was not the name of any 
 Athenian authority before their rule, 
 which it Avas in the reign of Hadrian 
 (see the law, lb. No. 355), and Uaroa- 
 TLoioL TOKoi is evidently a translation of 
 the Latin phrase usurce CentesimcB, as 
 in the Basilica, ix. 3, 87, and in Zona- 
 ras Gloss, p. C50, and therefore the 
 elacfiopa may be something totally dif- 
 
 otroi TO diaypa(f)€u dpyvpiou iv noXepco ! fereut from the ancient property tax, 
 fXTj €l(Te(f)€pov. I may observe in tliis I ius the word signifit-s any contribution 
 place that a fragment of an inscription I or direct tax whatever. We may ob-
 
 ClI. IX.] THE PROPERTY TAXES. 
 
 535 
 
 Moreover, if any person thought that he could show that he had 
 been unjustly included among the three hundred who paid the 
 taxes in advance, and that some other could with greater justice 
 be substituted in his place, the legal remedy for the aggrieved 
 party was the avrlhoai^ or exchange, to which the speech 
 against Phaenippus refers. 
 
 There still remain two points to be discussed, the explana- 
 tion of which we have intentionally deferred to the end of this 
 investigation. 
 
 In the first place, it appears singular that in the valuation 
 made in the year of Nausinicus a fixed sum, viz. 2500 drachmas, 
 was taken as the taxable capital for all persons indiscriminately; 
 and that it was then determined what portion of this amount 
 was in each class to be paid as a tax^'". For this I can find no 
 other reason than that this amount of property was the lowest 
 which came into consideration on the imposition of the tax; it 
 being fixed how much the valuation of each person should 
 amount to, if his property was only 2500 drachmas; and for 
 properties of greater amount, what the proprietor was to pay for 
 every 2500 drachmas. When Antipater made the rights of 
 citizenship depend upon the amount of property, the lowest 
 rate was 2000 drachmas, which agrees well with our assump- 
 tion. Demosthenes^^^ indeed asserts, that " whereas his family 
 used formerly to perform trierarchies, and to pay large property 
 taxes, now that he had only received from his guardians 31 
 minas and his father's house, by means of their shameless frauds 
 he could not even afford to pay small property taxes :^^ but an 
 expression of this kind, spoken in the feelings of bitterness, and 
 
 serve that from what is to a certain 
 degree intelligible in this inscription it 
 may be seen that at this period who- 
 ever did not pay this €la<popa, was 
 obliged to pay interest for it and pro- 
 vide sureties, and that after the expi- 
 
 XcDvrai irpcoTov fxcu eKaroa-- 
 
 Tiaicov t6k(jj[v] ac\) ov 8eov Troirjcraa-dai 
 T^v €la[cf)Of}a.jp ovK iTroir]aavTO, fi-^Xpi 
 jxrjvaiv aWoiv dvo rrjs reXevraias dnoSo- 
 crecoy. fiera Se tovs [fxrjvas] tovtovs et 
 fxevoKV fiT) 7r€i66p,€i'oi, aTTodoaOccxTav oi 
 
 ration of the term the property might apyvporaynaL pera rod KT]pvKos ras vtto- 
 
 be confiscated vvliich had been given OrjKas 7rpa>Tov piv tcov [prj] 
 
 as security; ""E-mTipiov opiC^Tcoaav av- dedcoKoroiv, elra kol twv eyyvt]Tav, Sic. 
 
 Tois Kara rrju rrjS dneiOias ci^iav. [eav '^'^'^ See book iv. ch. 7- 
 
 di] ela<i}€p€iv pr] ^ov- I '^^ C. Aphob. i. p. 833, 24, of. 825, (i.
 
 536 SYMMORI^ OF THE PROPERTY TAXES. [l3K. IV. 
 
 in the consciousness of the injury which he had sustained, 
 cannot be understood literally to mean that no taxes were im- 
 posed on a property of this amount; especially as it cannot be 
 denied, that a property tax upon so small an estate was oppres- 
 sive, and consequently a person might say that he could not 
 bear it, even if he was bound to pay it. 
 
 The other question is, for what reason Demosthenes**^ 
 should propose in two places that all should pay taxes, every 
 one in proportion to his property, if? as we have assumed, this 
 was already the case according to the actual regulations. As it 
 is the unpleasant duty of the inquirer into ancient history to 
 collect every expression that may be accidentally thrown out, 
 he is often unable to explain such indistinct allusions as these, 
 since the author wrote for contemporaries, and not for posterity. 
 At the same time, our orator gives thus much to be understood, 
 that the public administration was left to some; while others 
 were compelled to perform the trierarchy, to pay the taxes, and 
 to serve in the army; and he proposes that it should not be per- 
 mitted that one party should be always passing decrees merely 
 for the disadvantage of the other, as the injured one would be 
 always indolent, and never perform as much as was required of 
 it**^ But who then are these who administered the public 
 afifairs ? They can have been no others, as has been before 
 stated, than the three hundred in the symmorise, who composed 
 the pohtical parties. If then there were some who did not pay 
 taxes, these appear to have been the very persons; and if this 
 was in fact the case, the irregularity was at variance with the 
 principles of the constitution. It almost appears as if the 
 wealthiest in the symmoriee had at that time unjustly thrown 
 the burden upon the poorer, exactly as was the case in the 
 symmoriee of the trierarchy^*^ Let any person who may hope 
 to find a clue suggest some other solution of the difficulty. 
 
 Olyntli. i. p. 15, 1. "Eo-Tidrj \vi- fore the meaning of to 'laov of course 
 nop, olfxai, ndvTas elacf)€p€iv, av iroWtov is, one person like another, in equal pro- 
 de^ TToXXa, av oXiycov oXlya. Olynth. portion. 
 ii. p. 27, particularly in the words "6 oiynth. ii. ubi sup. 
 \ey(o8f} K€(l)a\aiou, nuvras d(T(f)€p€iv \ "7 See below, chap. 13. 
 a</) <ai/ cKaaros ix.€i to laov. Where- ;
 
 CII. X.] TAXES IMPOSED UPON RESIDENT ALIENS. 
 
 537 
 
 Chapter X. 
 
 The Property Taxes imposed upon, and the Liturgies performed 
 by, the resident Aliens, 
 
 We have hitherto been treating of the liturgies and the 
 taxes of the citizens, which fell upon (though only for the 
 property which they possessed in Attica), even if they lived 
 abroad*^". That those who had been created citizens {Stj/jlo- 
 irolrjTOL), such, for instance, as Pasion the rich banker, and 
 Apollodorus his son, paid taxes and were in the symmoriae 
 (unless, like Leucon, the king of the Bosporus, they had an 
 immunity), is hardly worth remarking; and the only reason 
 that Harpocration^*^ quotes out of Hyperides that the Btj/jlo- 
 TroLTjTot, were in the symmoriae of the trierarchy is, that they 
 were not admitted into the genea and phratriee, but only into 
 the tribes and demi. 
 
 But the resident aliens {/jbirocKoi) and the isoteles {[xeroLKOi 
 la-oreXeU) also performed public services which were different 
 from the liturgies of the citizens^^% and paid property taxes. 
 The resident aliens could, as well as the citizens, obtain an 
 exemption from the liturgies, particularly the choregia*^'; and 
 not only this, but there even occurs a case, apparently in the 
 age of Demosthenes, of some Sidonian citizens resident a 
 Athens having been allowed an exemption from the property 
 taxes^^'; at the same time we have but little knowledge of these 
 liturgies of the resident aliens. Their choregia, according to 
 the testimony of the Scholiast to Aristophanes^'% took place at 
 the Lensea: Lysias^'' speaks of the choregias which he had 
 performed; but, since he was an isoteles (though from what 
 
 *^» Demostli. c. Lept. § 31, fp. 46D, 
 5,)cf. §25, (p. 46G, 10 sqq.) 
 
 *-^ In V. avfifjiopia. 
 
 ^''o Thence /xeroiKcoi/ Xeirovpy'iai and 
 TToXiTiKui XeiTovpyLai. 
 
 ^* Deinosth. c. Lept. § 15 sqq. (p. 
 462, 13 sqq.) § 50, (p. 475, 23 sqq.) 
 Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 07 ad fin. 
 
 ^^^ Inscript. iiLi sup. Concerning 
 the dTiKels fieroiKoi, as Pollux (iii. 56,) 
 calls them, also see book iii. ch. 7 and 
 21. 
 
 =^33 piut. 954, where the doubts of 
 Ilenisterhuis are of no importance. 
 
 ^" C. Eratosth. p. 39G.
 
 538 TAXES IMPOSED UPON [bK. IV. 
 
 time we are ignorant), this does not prove that the common 
 resident aliens performed several choregias. Of the trierarchy 
 and gymnasiarchy of the resident aliens nothing is known; in 
 fact it is impossible to conceive that they existed. On the 
 other hand, an account in Ulpian*^^, taken from some ancient 
 commentator, that they provided a banquet (ecrrtacrt?) in the 
 same manner as the tribes, has every probability on its side, 
 since they had their own Jupiter (Zeu? f^eroUcos), and separate 
 religious rites, and consequently their own festivals, at which 
 banquettings of this kind used to be given. Lastly, there 
 remain to be mentioned the scaphephoria^^^ the hydriaphoria, 
 and sciadephoria, which were inferior and dishonourable ser- 
 vices imposed upon the resident aliens. 
 
 With regard to the property taxes, Lysias"', a resident 
 alien or an isoteles, boasts of having paid several; and they are 
 often mentioned in connexion with the resident alien s*^^ This 
 class of settlers composed distinct symmorise {/jberoifctKal (tv/ju- 
 fiopiai,y^^, which had treasurers of their own, and a fixed con- 
 tribution was settled for each one by persons appointed for that 
 purpose (e7rA7/)a<^ets')'^*°, which was of course only to be paid 
 upon the moveable property in Attica, since, with the excep- 
 tion of the proxeni and isoteles, no resident alien had the right 
 of possessing land. What however was the average amount of 
 this tax for any given rate cannot be determined; and there can 
 be no doubt that the total valuation of the resident aliens was 
 very different at different times, as they were not domiciliated 
 in Attica. Probably the larger number of them were poor. 
 As examples of rich aliens we may mention Dinarchus the 
 orator, Cephalus, and his sons Polemarchus and Lysias*^': the 
 latter not only had three houses and 120 slaves, but, in addi- 
 tion to vessels of silver and other articles of furniture and 
 
 '^ ^ Ad Lept. § 15. '^'^ Harpocration in v. eTrty/ja^ets-, 
 
 '^^ Lex. Seg. p. 280, p. 304, and Isocrat. Trapezit. 21 . 
 
 otliers. ^' Concerning Dinarchus see Dio- 
 
 * ' Ubi sup. i nysius Ilalicarnasscnsis in the Life of 
 
 ""» E. g. Lysius c. Frumentar. p. Diuarclius, and of the others Plat. 
 
 720. ' Itep. init. Lys. c. Eratosth. p. 380 sqq. 
 
 ''-^ llypehdes ap. Poll. viii. 11-1.
 
 CIl. X.] THE RESIDENT ALIENS. 539 
 
 manufactured goods, was possessed of 3 talents of silver, 400 
 cyzicenics, and 100 darics, in ready money. Other ricli aliens 
 are mentioned to have been executed by the Thirty Tyrants for 
 the sake of their property. It cannot be supposed that a large 
 sum could ever have been collected from them, however strict 
 the laws may have been against concealment, as their property 
 was easily concealed, and they were naturally ill-inclined to the 
 state'^*^ They were besides more severely pressed for money 
 than the citizens; hence Demosthenes speaks of the unfortu- 
 nate aliens : thus, for instance, in the tax levied during the 
 archonship of Nausinicus they contributed the sixth part^*^, 
 which is mentioned in such a manner that it is plain that this 
 was a higher rate than that which the poor citizens paid. The 
 tax in the year of Nausinicus was a twentieth, and are we to 
 suppose that while the citizens paid a twentieth, the resident 
 aliens contributed the sixth part of the valuation ? This cannot 
 appear probable. If a tax of a twentieth had been imposed 
 upon the taxable property of the citizens, a larger amount could 
 not have been raised from the resident ah ens, as the injustice 
 and severity of such a measure would have been too evident. 
 To understand with Ste. Croix^^* the sixth part of the property 
 itself is not less absurd than to suppose that the citizens paid a 
 fifth part. To contribute {ela<^epeiv) does not merely mean to 
 pay taxes, but to enter a certain taxable capital into the sym- 
 morise^^^ The citizens of the first class returned the fifth part 
 of their property as taxable capital; the other classes a smaller 
 part: the resident aliens however appear upon an average to 
 have been rated with the sixth part of their property, which 
 probably in the far greater number of cases was very 
 oppressive*. 
 
 Of the aliens who were resident in Attica there was a par- 
 
 ^■'^ Lys. c. Fiiiment. iibi sup. tions, i.\ xlviii. p. 185, in his Memoir 
 
 ■^*-^ Demosth. c. Androt. p. 612, upon the fieroiKoi. 
 7rpo(Tr]K€Lu avTa to €ktov fiepos €l(r(f)e- j "^^^ See above chap. 7j particularly 
 p€iv fxera rav fi€ToiK<ov. Cf. p. 609, I note 171. 
 
 * In England the rates of taxation 
 upon aliens were formerly double 
 those upon natives. Blackstone's 
 Commentaries, vol. i. p. 310. — Transl. 
 
 extr. where he uses the expression, 
 Toiii ToXcunoiipovs fxeToiKovs. 
 
 '^" Mem, do TAcad. des Inscrip-
 
 540 
 
 TAXES IMPOSED UPON 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 ticular portion that enjoyed certain rights and privileges called 
 Isotelia, the nature of which, on account of the scarcity of 
 information, is involved in some obscurity. The isoteles (tVo- 
 reXeh, ofjLoreXehy*^, after the proxeni, were next in rank to the 
 citizens, without being in fact citizens; they were neither 
 entered into the tribes and demi, nor into the phratriee and 
 genea; and, like other foreigners and resident aliens, they were, 
 together with the proxeni, subject to the jurisdiction of the 
 archon Polemarchus''*'. Hence it may be justly wondered how 
 so acute a writer as Wolf could imagine that they had the right 
 of voting, and were eligible to public offices"^. No one but a 
 citizen could vote in the Assembly, and for this it was necessary 
 that he should have been entered into a tribe and demus: in 
 like manner no isoteles could sit in a court of justice. The 
 testimony of Ammonius and Thomas Magister, who assert that 
 they had all the privileges of citizens, with the exception of the 
 offices of government, is wholly undeserving of credit, unless 
 among the offices of government {to dpx^tv) they include, con- 
 trary to the usual custom, the rights of voting and judging {to 
 €KK\r]ai,d^€cv kol hiKa^eiv). With regard to the latter point, 
 indeed, they certainly had some privileges; for they could be 
 appointed disetetee^*®: it is however by no means probable that 
 they could have been appointed by lot public dieetetse ; since 
 there can be no doubt that they had no patron {irpoaTdTT^s), 
 which is evident without any express testimony; they could 
 transact business directly with the people and the proper autho- 
 rities, without it being necessary for that reason that they 
 should have the right of voting in the public assembly. They 
 had moreover the right of possessing both land and mines"*'. 
 With regard to the liturgies and taxes, they were, as their name 
 shows, on the same footing as the citizens; they neither paid 
 
 *^*' Pollux iii. 5G. Coiiceraing them 
 in general see also the Memoir of Ste. 
 Croix above cited. 
 
 2^' Pollux \-iii. 91. 
 
 ^^8 Wolf, p. Ixix. sq. 
 
 ^<° Deniosth. c. I'horni. p. 912, extr. 
 See Uudtwalcker von den Diiitcteu, p. 
 
 2, ■svho in pp. 40 sqq. makes it pro- 
 bable, from the authority of Suidas, 
 that aliens could not be public diaiteta?. 
 An isoteles was liowever only a /xeVot- 
 Kosy and so far an alien. 
 ^i« Book i. ch. 24, iii. cli. 3.
 
 CH. X.] THE RESIDENT ALIENS. 541 
 
 any protection-money, nor were they subject to the same obli- 
 gations as the resident aliens^^', but were upon the same level 
 with the citizens"^; and from these taxes they could be 
 exempted in the same manner as the citizens, for the law of 
 Leptines expressly mentions the exemption of the isoteles. 
 Their valuation must therefore have been entered in the register 
 of the citizens, more particularly as they possessed landed pro- 
 perty ; and it was according to this rate that they paid property 
 taxes, and not accordmg to the scale of the resident aliens. 
 With regard to the liturgies, they were unquestionably exempted 
 from the degrading services performed by the resident aliens; 
 and in reference to this point, as well as to the military service, 
 they may have been entered in the registers of the tribes. 
 Moreover, as to whether the isoteles, as is asserted*^^, were 
 compelled to give a larger sum for these distinctions, or whether 
 they gave less than the resident aliens"^, a determinate judg- 
 ment appears impossible, since, according to the different cir- 
 cumstances of the case, either the one or the other may have 
 existed. It is however evident that in the property taxes the 
 majority of the citizens, with whom the isoteles were equal, 
 were rated lower than the resident aliens. A more exact 
 account as to the obligations of the isoteles with regard to the 
 liturgies, was contained in the speech of Isseus against Elpa- 
 goras, which is unfortunately lost**^. 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 General Nature of the Trierarchy, 
 
 We will now proceed to consider the extraordinary liturgy, the 
 trierarchy, which, although it has been frequently treated of by 
 
 25'- Harpocrat. in v. laoTeXrjs. Lex. Seg. p. 207 upon this subject is 
 
 '^^ This is the reXos copLcrfJieuov, of quite correct : 'lo-oreXeis : fxeroiKoi ra 
 
 which Suidas (in v. IcroTeXrjs) speaks, fiev ^eviKO. reXtj fir] reXovvrei, ra 6e taa 
 
 i. e. a duty detemiined according to toIs aarots reXovvres. See also Pho- 
 
 the valuation, when the time occurred. , tins. 
 
 The other passages of the gramma- | "^ Wolf, p. Ixi. 
 
 rians and modern writers may be seen , ^^^ See Ste. Croix, p. 190. 
 
 in Wolf, p. Ixx. The article in the ^^^ Harpocrat. in v. laoreXrfs.
 
 542 GENERAL NATURE OF [bK. IV. 
 
 the early scholars*'', and its nature more fully ascertained by 
 the inquiries of Wolf, must nevertheless be submitted to a new 
 examination, in order to explain what the person who provided 
 it furnished to the state; what changes it underwent in the 
 different periods, and when these took place ; and, lastly, what 
 proportion the services bore to the property of the trierarch. 
 
 The object of this liturgy was to provide for the equipment 
 and management of the ships of war. AYhoever undertook it, 
 was called, by virtue of his office, trierarch, and attended the 
 ship wherever it vrent in person, or, what is the same, by means 
 of a deputy. This institution produced great advantages to the 
 state, on account of the competition to fill the office of trierarch ; 
 but since in war the opportunity of victory, if not seized when 
 it presents itself, will not wait for the dilatoriness of the com- 
 batants, the favourable instant was frequently lost, by the want 
 of dispatch necessarily connected with the trierarchy*^'; and 
 since the division of the burdens was frequently made upon 
 unfair principles (until Demosthenes introduced the only just 
 method of allotment), many individuals were grievously 
 oppressed. The first disadvantage they sometimes remedied 
 by appointing trierarchs beforehand, especially in early times. 
 And we may, in the first place, consider that the duties of those 
 to whom Themistocles transferred the building of the ships, 
 were of this kind"^; and again, the trierarchs who in Olymp. 
 87 2, (B.C. 431), were required to provide the 100 triremes, 
 which were always to be kept prepared for the defence of Attica, 
 in case of an attack by sea^^^; and, lastly, the 400 annual trie- 
 rarchs mentioned in Xenophon^'". But in Olymp. 107, 1^ 
 (B.C. 352), when Demosthenes delivered the first Philippic, the 
 
 25G I may mention Sigonius (de Rep. and Bartlielemy (Auacliarsip, t. iv. 
 
 Atli. iv. 4), Avho is so clear on all the chap. 56). 
 
 other subjects which lie has treated, "'^ Demosth. Philipp. i. p. 50, 18. 
 Petit, who is always confused (Leg. ^^^ Polyoen. Strateg. i. 30, 5. The 
 
 Att. iii. 4), Budseus (de asse et parti- other passages relating to this point, 
 
 bus ejus V. p. 531 sqq.), SchefFer (Mil. and some observations suggested by 
 
 Nav. ii. 4, and particularly vi. 6), them, may be seen in ray Dissertation 
 
 Toun-eil (Notes to his Translation of upon the Silver Mines of Laurium. 
 the Oration for the Crown in his ^^^ Thucyd. ii. 24. 
 Works, Paris, 1721, t. iv, p. 501 sqq.), ^"^ Xenoph. Kep. Ath. 3, 4.
 
 cri. XI.] 
 
 THE TRIERARCHY. 
 
 543 
 
 appointment of the trierarchs did not take place till the fleet 
 should have been in readiness to sail*^'. They were nominated 
 by the generals, who^^^, as being the legal authorities for miUtary 
 affairs, brought the causes relating to the trierarchy into court. 
 
 The amount of expense was unquestionably fixed according 
 to the rate actually required by law, by means of the dia- 
 gramma of the trierarchy. If any one thought that he was too 
 heavily burdened in comparison with another who could bear 
 the liturgy better than himself, the avTihocns^ or exchange, was 
 open to him. In extreme cases they fled for refuge to the 
 people, or to the altar of Diana at Munychia"^ Those who 
 were in arrear could be put into prison by certain officers, 
 whose duty it was to expedite the business relating to the 
 trierarchy, and to despatch the fleet [ol airoardXelsY^*. On 
 the other hand, whichever trierarch first brought his ship off 
 the stocks, or distinguished himself in any other way, received 
 as a reward the crown of the trierarchy; on which account a 
 considerable degree of competition existed between the different 
 individuals. The trierarch was also exempted by law from all 
 other liturgies^^^, the advance of the property taxes included. 
 
 The duration of the trierarchy was limited by law to one 
 year, after which the successor elect {hidhoxo^) entered upon 
 the office. The latter was obliged to join the ship, in case it 
 was absent, and to take charge of it and succeed to the duties 
 of his predecessor, on pain of a severe penalty in case of non- 
 compliance. If any one had continued his trierarchy beyond 
 the legal period, he could charge the additional expenses, which 
 he was no longer bound to pay [tov iTTLTpcrjpapxvfJ'CiTos), to his 
 successor*^'. The trierarchy was legally dissolved, if the 
 
 •^'" Demosth. ubi sup. 
 
 ^^^^^Demosth. c. Lacrit. p. 940, IG, 
 c. Boeot. de Nomine, p. 997, 2, conip. 
 Suidas in the passage quoted by ISIat- 
 tliige Misc. Philol. vol. i. p. 249. 
 
 ^63 Demosth. de Corona, p. 262, 15, 
 and there Ulpian. Concerning the 
 place see Lysias, c. Agorat. p. 460. 
 
 ^^ Demosth. ubi sup. and there 
 Taylor, also Demosth. de Coron. Trie- 
 
 I rarch. p. 1229, 6, where the orator 
 mentions a decree by which it was 
 ordained that tliose persons should be 
 imprisoned who did rfot bring their 
 vessel to the pier (x^H-"-) before the 
 last day of the month. 
 
 2«^ Bookiii. ch. 21. 
 
 ■'''6 Demosth. c. Polycl. To tliis the 
 article in Lex. Sex. refers (diK. ovofi. 
 p. 193, 30,) TpirjptipxVH-fi '• ^i'"*' o Tpirj-
 
 544 
 
 GENERAL NATURE OF 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 general gave out no pay to the sailors, and also if the ship had 
 run into the Piraeus, as then it was not possible to keep the 
 crew together''". In general no person was bound to serve a 
 liturgy for more than the alternate years ^^''; but in the later 
 times of Isaeus*^^, the citizens could only be compelled to 
 serve the trierarchy after an interval of two years, although 
 many made no use of this immunity. 
 
 Exemption from the trierarchy was prohibited by an ancient 
 law, which was still in force in Olymp. 106, 2 (b.c. 355), when 
 Demosthenes spoke against Lei)tines ; nor was it even allowed 
 to the successors of Harmodius and Aristogiton ; it was, how- 
 ever, granted to the nine archons, as being the highest public 
 officers'^^'*; whence it is easy to see that nothing but necessity 
 induced them 'to except those whose property was below the 
 amount required for the trierarchy. Demosthenes also evi- 
 dently leaves out of his consideration those exemptions which 
 were not personal, but founded upon causes sanctioned by law ; 
 the abolition of which appears not to have even come within 
 the scheme of Leptines, since the orator would not have failed 
 to touch upon this point. Demosthenes, in the speech con- 
 cerning the symmoriee^^', which was delivered in Olymp. 106, 
 3 (b.c. 354), mentions the circumstances under which a citizen 
 w^as exempted from the trierarchy. These were if a person was 
 incapable [ahvvaTos) ; by which we certainly must not under- 
 stand bodily incapacity (which could only have exempted from 
 
 papxos nepicrcrov 6i5a)cri ro7s. vavraii ; 
 an extremely incorrect explanation, 
 but not too incorrect for the compiler 
 of this Lexicon. The proper name is 
 moreover iiriTpir^pdpxqp.a, and not 
 Tpirjpdpx'TJP'a.- Photius in v. TpiTjpap- 
 XVH'" gives a somewhat better inter- 
 pretation, 
 
 ^•^7 Demosth. ibid. p. 1209. Cf. 
 Isocrat. c Callim. 23. 
 
 ^^^ 'EviavTov ?)LaXnro>u, says Demos- 
 thenes against Leptines. See book iii. 
 ch. 21. 
 
 ■^^ Isaeus de Apollod. Hered. p. 184, 
 8uo ^TT] /caraXiTTci)!/. See also b. iii. c.22. 
 
 270 Demosth. c. Lept. § 15 (p. 462, 
 15), § 22 (p. 4G4, 29), § 23 (p. 465, 18). 
 
 271 P. 182, 14. That the following 
 words are neuter is shown by the ex- 
 pression opcpaviKwv, wliich, if the mas- 
 culine gender were meant, would be 
 6p(}>ava)v. Pollux iniderstood this 
 point correctly, as well as Harpocra- 
 tion in v. k\t]pqv)(oi ; but the same 
 grammarian in v. koivcovikwv inaccu- 
 rately considers this word as masculine. 
 Cf Poll. viii. 134, 136. Photius in 
 Kkrjpovxoi and koivwvikuv has only 
 transcribed Harpocration.
 
 CH. XI.] THE TRIERARCHY. 545 
 
 personal services, and not from contributions to the symmoriee), 
 but insufficiency of property, since a man of sufficient property 
 for the trierarchy might by misfortune be reduced in his 
 circumstances; also the property of heiresses {iiriK\7]poi), of 
 wards {6p<paviKa), of cleruchi {Kkr)pov')(^LKa), and of companies 
 {fcoivoiVLKa)', for which exemptions he deducts altogether 800 
 persons from the 2000 whom he proposes to bring into the 
 symmoriee of the trierarchy. It is natural to suppose that 
 heiresses could only be exempted so long as they remained 
 unmarried ; if the heiress was married, the husband bore the 
 burdens and obligations attached to the property, as in the 
 case of the dowry. Wards were free from all liturgies during 
 their minority, and one year over^^*; hence Demosthenes, for 
 the ten years that he was in the hands of guardians, paid 
 property taxes, but no hturgies ; nor did he perform any 
 trierarchy, although his family was capable of supporting the 
 expenses of that service^'% and he himself became a trierarch 
 after the expiration of his minority. By the property of 
 cleruchi, Harpocration, perhaps, rightly understands the pro- 
 perty of those who were sent out by the state as cleruchi, or 
 colonists, and while they were absent upon the public service 
 could not perform the trierarchy. I should, however, conjecture 
 that the exemption was limited to the property which they had 
 taken with them. What kind of property is meant by the 
 property of companies admits of some doubt. Pollux ^^* 
 states that it was a legal term, and classes it with other words 
 which signify a property in common, and not of individuals ; 
 by which explanation little is gained. The most probable 
 conjecture is that in Harpocration, viz., that the property of 
 brothers, which had not yet been divided among them, is 
 meant, from which the father might be able to perform the 
 liturgy, although the sons were not sufficiently rich separately 
 to bear the expenses of trierarchy '^\ Perhaps, he adds, it 
 
 27^ Lysias c. Diogit. p. 908. I ^'' Cf. Orat. c. Euerg. et :Muesibul. 
 
 '^''' Demosth. c. Apliob. p. 833, 26. | p. 1149, 20, hp^M^ "^'to''. TvorfpajxeiLc- 
 Cf. Liician. Demostli/Eiilog. U. fuafxevos c'tq npos tov dbeXcpbv, rj koivtj 
 
 '■^^^ viii. 134, where it is joined with ' oucrta ea; ot^roT?, and immediately after- 
 dviixrjTo xpni^ara, Kol Koiva, iirUoLva, ov wards, on pevefirjficvos e'lq- 
 8u]prifi€ua. 2 N
 
 546 GENERAL NATURE OF [bK. IV. 
 
 may refer to persons who had entered into a voluntary associa- 
 tion for trade, or for any other object, each member of which 
 was possessed of less than the whole valuation of the property 
 of the company. Is it, however, conceivable that persons in 
 this situation could have ever obtained an exemption by such 
 means; since, had it been the case, every person would have so 
 disposed of his property, or have vested it in similar associa- 
 tions, in order to exempt himself from the liturgies ? Lastly, 
 it hardly deserves to be observed, that mines, since they could 
 not be exchanged, did not impose upon their possessors the 
 duty of serving the trierarchy. 
 
 A peculiarity wdth respect to the trierarchy, which must not 
 be passed over, is the liability of the trierarchs to render an 
 account of their expenses^^^, which naturally excites our asto- 
 nishment, when we find it remarked in ^schines that the 
 trierarch applied his own property to the service of the com- 
 munity in a manner unknown to the public; yet our surprise 
 is diminished, and we perceive that the provisions of the law 
 were both wise and necessary, when w^e consider how manifold 
 were the relations in which the trierarch stood to the state with 
 regard to money and money's worth. The ship he always 
 received from the state, and at times ready equipped; and are 
 we to suppose that he was not required to account for this 
 public property? He also received money out of the public 
 treasury, whether it was for the payment of the sailors and 
 soldiers, or other expenses. Thus we find in Demosthenes 30 
 minas paid to each trierarch, and an equal sum is stated in an 
 inscription, the date of which is Olymp. 92, 3 (b.c. 410), to 
 have been given to a trierarch^^^ Thus even in the age of 
 Themistocles the receipts from the mines were distributed 
 among a number of rich men, at the rate of a talent apiece, in 
 order to build and equip vessels for the use of the state. The 
 trierarch supplied pay and provision money to the whole crew, 
 which the general was bound to provide him with^^% or he 
 
 276 JEschin. c. Ctesipli. p. 407 sq. 
 Deraosth. c. Polycl. p. 1222, 11. 
 
 ^77 Demostli. de Trierarch. Coron. 
 
 p. 1231, 13, Corp. Inscript. No. 147, 
 Pryt. 9. 
 
 ^7*^ Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1209, 10.
 
 CH. XI.] 
 
 HE TRIERARCHY. 
 
 547 
 
 furnished the necessary stores'^'^ which were paid for at the 
 public cost. 
 
 Those also who were appointed to manage the accounts 
 were called treasurers of the trierarchs^^% although we are 
 ignorant whether all vessels, or only the sacred triremes, had 
 officers of this description; nor can it be inferred from the 
 statement of Demosthenes^ client in the oration against Poly- 
 cles^^^, who himself kept the accounts of his expenses in tlie 
 trierarchy, that he had no treasurer. In the case of the 
 trierarchs of the sacred triremes, it was still more natural that 
 they should be responsible for their expenses, as the state was 
 there the party that performed the liturgy^^^ The fund be- 
 longing to these triremes, which was under the management of 
 the treasurer, and from which all the expenses were defrayed, 
 was a public fund. Trierarchs of this description^^^ were only 
 the representati^'es of the state in the character of commanders 
 and officers; and how large the sums were which they received, 
 we see from the instances of the trierarchs of the trireme Sala- 
 minia, and of the Delian theoris, which latter, for the voyage to 
 Delos alone, received 7000 drachmas from the funds of the 
 temple in that island. 
 
 Supposing however that the trierarch paid everything at his 
 own expense (though he was by no means bound to do so, and 
 it was an event of rare occurrence), even then it was necessary 
 that he should inform the state of his course of proceeding, and 
 deliver in an account, which would merely have stated that no 
 public money had been advanced to him, and would have given 
 him an opportunity of defending himself, if any one called his 
 
 "'^ Plutarch, de Gloria Athenarum, 
 6. 
 
 ^*' Eupolis ap. Harpocrat. in v. ra- 
 fiiai, and the grammarians who tran- 
 scribe him. [Meineke, Fr.Com. Gr.vol. 
 ii. p. 505]. Compare too particularly 
 book ii. ch. 6, note 94. 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1216, 15. 
 
 ^* Ulpian ad Demosth. c. Mid. p. 
 636, ed. Wolf. 
 
 ^^^ In order that there may be no 
 
 doubt as to the fact of the sacred tri- 
 remes having trierarchs, I may men- 
 tion the trierarchs of the Salaminia in 
 Plutarch Themist. 7, of the Paralos in 
 Isseus de Dicseog. Hered. p. 90, and of 
 the Delian theoris in Corp. Inscript. 
 No. 158. No ship of war could be 
 without a trierarch; for he not only 
 provided for the expenses, but also 
 commanded the vessel. 
 
 2 N 2
 
 548 
 
 FIRST AND SECOND FORMS OF 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 statement in question. And, lastly, it was probably necessary 
 for the trierarch to show that he had performed the required 
 services correctly. 
 
 Chapter XII. 
 
 First Form of the Trierarchy, or the Trierarchy of a single 
 Person, Second Form of the Trierarchy, or the Trierarchy 
 in part of a single Person and in part of two Syntrierarchs, 
 from Olymp. 92, 1 (b.c. 412) until Olymp. 105,3 (b.c. 358). 
 
 The trierarchy is as ancient as the regular constitution of 
 Athens, since it is mentioned in the time of Hippias^^*, and it 
 probably belonged originally to the forty-eight naucrarias of 
 Solon and the fifty naucrarias of Cleisthenes, according to some 
 fixed regulation, since each naucraria was obliged to equip a 
 ship*^^; so that the trierarchy of each tribe would have been of 
 5 vessels. But when the naval force was gradually increased 
 to 200 vessels, which was the number at sea at the time of the 
 battle of Salamis, the trierarchs also became more numerous. 
 
 For a long time each ship had only one trierarch; subse- 
 quently it was allowed that two persons should fill the office 
 together {crvvTpLrjpap')(OL, <7vvTpt7jpap')(^ovvT€S'), in order to divide 
 the expenses, and either of them commanded on board the 
 vessel for diflferent portions of the year, as they agreed with one 
 another*®^ When this was first permitted we are not informed; 
 since however in Olymp. 92, 1 (b.c. 412), after the defeat in 
 
 *«^ Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. 2, 4. 
 
 '^^^ See Look ii. ch. 21. NavKpapoi 
 are properly ship proprietors {vavKXr)- 
 pot) or their deputies ; the following 
 appears to have been the method by 
 which it happened that this name was 
 given to the managers of the political 
 associations, which were afterwards 
 replaced by the demi. The Athenian 
 citizens were first distributed into 
 forty-eight, and afterwards into fifty 
 corporations, and to each of these a ship 
 was allotted, which they were bound to 
 man. They then selected some one 
 
 member of the corporate body, who, 
 either alone, or with the support of 
 the rest, had in his turn the duty of 
 equipping the ship, and thus was for 
 the time being possessor of the ship 
 (vavKXrjpof, vavKpapos), and the com- 
 pany allotted to hira was the naucaria 
 or naucraria (naucleria), of which he 
 naturally was the principal person. 
 Photius properly compares the nau- 
 crarias with the symmorise. 
 
 ^«« Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1219, sup. 
 p. 1229, extr.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 THE TRIERARCHY. 
 
 549 
 
 Sicily^ the union of two persons for the choregia was allowed*^^, 
 the same may have been permitted at the same period for the 
 more expensive trierarchy. The most ancient accomit of a 
 trierarchy performed jointly by two persons, or a syntrierarchy, 
 is later than Olymp. 92, 3 (b.c. 410), since Lysias speaks 
 of the syntrierarchy which the guardian accounted for to 
 the brothers of Diogiton, who perished at Ephesus under 
 Thrasyllus in Olymp. 92, 3 (b.c. 410)^*°: the next, which is in 
 Isocrates^^^ belongs to the year of the battle of ^gospotamos 
 (Olymp. 93, 3, B.C. 406) ; and the same form of the trierarchy 
 is alluded to in a passage in Xenophon^**", which refers to some 
 time anterior to Olymp. 95, 1 (b.c. 400). This usage continued 
 for a very long period : for when Demosthenes instituted the 
 suit against Aphobus (Olymp. 104, 1, B.C. 364), we still meet 
 wdth the syntrierarchy^^ ^; also in Olymp. 104,4 (b.c. 361)^^% 
 and even so late as in Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358). The latter 
 year is that of the Euboean war, in which the Athenians sup- 
 ported a party against the other states, and against Thebes'*'^"'; 
 and there were then at Athens for the first time voluntary 
 trierarchs, the terms of service for those appointed by law 
 having expired^®*. Demosthenes, who was one of them, had a 
 
 287 Book iii. ch. 21. Manso (Sparta, 
 vol. ii. p. 501) also supposes that there 
 were four trierarchs to one ship, by 
 erroneously combining diflFerent ac- 
 counts which have no connexion with 
 each other. 
 
 288 Lys. c.Diogit. pp. 907—909. The 
 date may be seen from pp. 894 — 897, 
 compared with Xenoph. Hell. i. 2. 
 
 289 Isocrat. c. Callimach.23. 
 
 290 See chap. 15, at the end. 
 
 29' Demosth. c. IMid. p. 564, 20, cf. 
 c. Aphob. ii. p. 840, 26, sqq. c. Mid. p. 
 539, extr. 
 
 292 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1218, 14, 
 cf. p. 1219 sup. and 1. 18, also p. 1227. 
 
 29-J Diod. xvi. 7. The following pas- 
 sages in Demosthenes also refer to this 
 fact, c. Androt. p. 597, 18, pro Mega- 
 lop, p. 205, 25, de Cherson. p. 108, 12, 
 c. Mid. p. 570, 23, ore ttjv eVt OrjlBaiovs 
 €^o8ov els Ev^oiav eVoificr^e v/xeis. 
 
 where Ulpian correctly notes, eyeVero 
 yap Koi 8ia tov UXovTapxov irepa : for 
 the expedition made for the sake of 
 Plutarch is not alluded to, concerning 
 which see chap. 13, but that which 
 took place in Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358). 
 For in the expedition of Olymp, 106, 
 4 (b.c. 353), Meidias was trierarch of 
 his vessel at his own expense, but in 
 the earlier expedition was treasurer of 
 the Paralos. Spalding (ad Mid. p. 
 131) corrects the passage of Ulpian 
 without any reason ; for the only way 
 in which he can be imderstood is, that 
 he supposed that more than one cam- 
 paign was undertaken for the sake of 
 Plutarch ; he does not however appear 
 to have had any clear notion of the 
 question. 
 
 29^ Demosth. de Corona, p. 259, 12, 
 c. Mid. p. 566, 23.
 
 550 
 
 FIRST AND SECOND FORMS OF 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 syntrierarch by name Philinus^"; and although this was a 
 voluntary service, yet there can be no doubt that it followed 
 upon the whole the regulations which were then in existence 
 for the regular trierarchy. Also in the oration against Euergus 
 and AInesibulus^^% mention is made in connexion with an event 
 of Olymp. 105, 4 (b.c. 357), of two syntrierarchs by name 
 Theophemus and Demochares, who were indebted to the state 
 for ship^s furniture belonging to a prior trierarchy, and thus 
 this syntrierarchy could only have been performed a short time 
 before, for instance, in the second, or more probably in the 
 third, year of the 105th Olympiad (b.c. 359 — 8); nor, lastly, 
 can it appear strange that even after the introduction of the 
 symmorice two syntrierarchs should have been employed for 
 the immediate direction of the trierarchy. 
 
 It is perhaps scarcely worthy of remark, that the syntrierarchy 
 of two persons was at most only a means of relief, in case there 
 did not happen to be a sufficient number of wealthy citizens 
 who could singly bear the expense, and numerous examples 
 occur between Olymp. 92, 1 and 105, 3 (b.c. 412 — 358)3 of 
 trierarchies performed by one individual; of which I will only 
 mention that of Apollodorus in Olymp. 104, 3 (b.c. 362)^^^; 
 and in two passages of Iseeus, which refer to this period, the 
 trierarchy of individuals and the syntrierarchy are mentioned as 
 contemporaneous^^^ It is therefore not difficult to conceive 
 that during this period about 400 trierarchs may have been 
 employed every year, which is the number stated by Xenophon 
 (or whoever is the author of the Treatise on the State of 
 Athens) as being annually appointed. 
 
 Concerning the services to which the trierarch was liable 
 
 '-95 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 566, 24. 
 
 •296 p^ 1145, 22sqq.where7roXi!'i/ ;;^po- 
 vov (p. 1146, 20) must only be taken 
 relatively, foi* it cannot mean any long 
 period of time. 
 
 ^^7 Demosth. c. Poly clem. 
 
 298 De Dicgeog. Herod, p. 110, dWa 
 
 fMTfV TpirjpdpXOOV TO(TOVT(jiV KaTafTTaOiV- 
 
 TOiV OVT avTos €TpLT]pcipxr}(T€U ovff irepco 
 av/x^e/^XrjKei/ eV toIs toiovtois Kiupois 
 
 (after the Anarchy). 2v/i/3aXXfti/ is 
 said of the syntrierarchy, cf. a~vp.^a- 
 Xeadai ap. Lys. c. Diogit. pp. 908, 909, 
 also Isseus de Apollod. Ilered. p. 184, 
 6 jjLev yap TraTrjp avrov — Tpir)papxS>v TOU 
 ndvTa xpdvov SiereXcaev, ovk ck crvfjifio- 
 pias TTjv vavv TTOir](Tdp.evos axrirep ol vvv 
 (after Olymp. 105, 4, b.c. 357), JXX' e/c 
 Toiv uvTov dairavcov, ovde devrepos avros 
 o)v dXXd Kara p,6vas.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 THE TRIERARCHY. 
 
 551 
 
 previously to Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358), there cannot exist the 
 slightest doubt. The state always supplied the vessel. When 
 Themistocles built ships for the JEginetan war out of the funds 
 accruing from the mines, the building and the entire equipment 
 of them was delivered in charge to 100 wealthy individuals, 
 who were the trierarchs appointed for that service ; but they 
 were indemnified for the building, since, according to Polysenus, 
 they each received a talent. This law of Themistocles enacted 
 that twenty new ships should be built every year, and the ship- 
 building was continued on the part of the state, as far as we can 
 ascertain, during the independence of Athens"^ All the ships 
 in the public docks belonged to the state : private individuals 
 of great wealth had indeed triremes of their own, for example, 
 Cleinias, who fought in his own vessel at Artemisium; but 
 since it is particularly remarked^^" that he went out with a 
 trireme of his own, it may be inferred that the state was bound 
 by law to provide it. Those which were in the possession of 
 private individuals, they either built voluntarily for the public 
 service, or for their own use in privateering or similar objects, or 
 else for sale. The same was the case in the Peloponnesian war. 
 The 100 triremes which, according to a decree of the people, 
 were to be kept in readiness from Olymp. 87, 2 (b.c. 431), in 
 case Attica was threatened by sea, were evidently ships pro- 
 vided by the state, and trierarchs were appointed for those in 
 readiness^*'^ In the Knights of Aristophanes""^ (Olymp. 88, 4, 
 B.C. 425), Cleon threatens to make his adversary a trierarch, 
 and to contrive that he should receive an old ship with a rotten 
 mast, upon which he would be forced to spend much money for 
 the necessary repairs; it is therefore certain that the hull and 
 mast were at that time furnished by the state. In the expe- 
 dition against Sicily in Olymp. 91, 2 (b.c. 415), the state pro- 
 vided nothing but the pay of the crew, and the body of the 
 vessel; the trierarchs supplied the entire equipment of the ship, 
 and also gave voluntary contributions^"^; and when a trierarch 
 
 ^^^ Concerning the building of the 
 ships, see book ii. ch. 19. 
 
 ^fo Herod, viii. 17, Plutarch. Alci- 
 biad. i. 
 
 ^°' This is the only manner in wliich 
 Thucyd. ii. 24 can be understood. 
 30^ Vs. 908 sqq. 
 '•^^^ Thucyd. vi. 31.
 
 552 FIRST AND SECOND FORMS OF [bK. IV. 
 
 boasts of having, after the battle of ^gospotamos (Olymp. 
 93, 3, B.C. 40G)''% saved his ship, it is clear that the vessel must 
 have been pubUc property, as otherwise he would have gained 
 no credit by saving it. The same person also states that he 
 and his brother had voluntarily contributed the pay and pro- 
 vision of the crew. We may conclude then that at this time 
 the state furnished both the pay and provision, as well as the 
 hull of the ship together with the mast; the trierarch however 
 had to equip the vessel, and was also bound, as the threat of 
 Cleon shows, to keep it in repair. 
 
 We may likewise infer that the same regulations were in 
 force until Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358), although the inaccurate 
 expressions of the ancients, who always presuppose more in 
 their readers than they have the means of knowing, have deceived 
 all modern writers from the ignorant Ulpian down to the acute 
 editor of the oration against Leptines. Demosthenes in his 
 speech against Meidias^"^^ says, that when he was trierarch in 
 Olymp. 104, 1 (b.c. 364), the trierarchs provided everything at 
 their own expense, and had to furnish the crews (TrXrjpcofjLara) ; 
 and if we are to give credit to the remarks of Ulpian upon this 
 passage^°% the state must frequently have supplied both the ship 
 and the seamen; and in fact in many instances have provided 
 nothing, but left it to the trierarch to supply the ship together 
 with the pay and provision of the crew. The real state of the 
 case, however, is as follows. Ulpian, as usual, has no authority 
 for his statement, but by a singular process of logic draws all 
 these conclusions from the words of Demosthenes. The orator 
 however, in speaking of the whole expenditure, refers to the 
 later form of the trierarchy in symmorise; when these were 
 instituted, the state equipped the vessel and provided the crew, 
 in addition to^ which the trierarch who commanded the ship 
 received pecuniary assistance from the symmoria; it follows 
 therefore that the whole expense did not fall upon him. Again, 
 when the orator speaks of the whole expenditure, it is evident 
 that he can only mean the entire amount of expenditure which 
 
 ^^* Isocrat. c. Callimacli. 23. ^"^ P. 564, 22. 
 
 ""5 r. UfJO A.
 
 CH. XII.] THE TillERARCHY. 553 
 
 was customary at any time; the state however always provided 
 the pay and provision together with the hull of the ship, as well 
 before the trierarchy of Demosthenes, as in the time of the 
 symmoriee. Thus no one of the hearers of Demosthenes could 
 have thought that these expenses were alluded to. In short, 
 when Demosthenes speaks of the whole expenditure, he means 
 nothing more than the equipment of the vessel, and the keep- 
 ing it in repair, as well as procuring the crew, which last was 
 frequently attended with much expense, as the trierarch, not 
 being allowed to employ foreign sailors, was obliged to select 
 the crew from the native population, which produced consider- 
 able trouble and vexation, and subjected the trierarch tothe 
 necessity of giving bounties to induce persons to serve. Even 
 in Olymp, 104, f (b.c. 361), the state was bound by law to 
 equip the ship. 
 
 That this must have been the meaning of the orator is 
 partly evident from the expenses of his trierarchy, and partly 
 from the speech against Polycles. When Demosthenes had 
 attained his majority, and begun to prosecute his guardians, 
 Thrasylochus, the brother of Meidias, wished to compel him 
 either to the exchange of property, or else to take the trierarchy. 
 Demosthenes was wiUing to adopt the former course, reserving, 
 at the same time, his claims upon his guardians; it being how- 
 ever necessary to confirm this agreement by a judicial decision 
 which could not be obtained in a short time, he volimtarily 
 undertook the trierarchy, which was let to a contractor for 20 
 minas^"^; it was, however, a syn trierarchy^" % so that the whole 
 
 307 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 539 sq. C. bers, each of whom contributed 20 
 Aphob. ii. p. 840 sq. This Thrasy- minas, in order tliat he might make 
 lochus was himself trierarch three ; the sum a talent, since it is stated in 
 years later, 01>Tnp. 104, 4, Orat. c. i one other place, that a person had let 
 
 Polycl. p. 1222. 
 
 3»8 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 564, 20. 
 Kayo) ft€i/ Kar' eiceivovs tovs ;^pdi'ous 
 cTpiTjpdpxovv, evdvs eK naihcov e^eXdav, 
 
 his trierarchy to a contractor for a 
 talent. As if this had been a fixed 
 price, and Demosthenes did not dis- 
 tinctly say that there were only two 
 
 oT€ avvbvo ^/xei/ ol rpirjpapxoi, &c. trierarchs ! Spalding also ad Mid. p. 
 From this passage too Ulpian has de- i 43, has been led into error. It may be 
 duced some ingenious conclusions ; | observed that the words in the speech 
 tlms (p. 660 E— G) he supposes that against Meidias, p. 540, 18, ocrot rrpi 
 there existed a syntelia of three mem- | Tpirjpapxiav riaav fiefxiadaxoTeSt refer
 
 554 
 
 FIRST AND SECOND FORMS OF 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 trierarchy only cost 40 minas. Can it, however, be conceived 
 that this was the whole expense of a trierarchy, if the ship, 
 pay, and provision were supplied by the trierarch, the cost of 
 pay and provision for one month alone being as much as that 
 sum? Moreover the speech against Polycles, which belongs to 
 Olymp. 104, f (B.C. 361), contains the best information con- 
 cerning the services which were required by law at that time. 
 There is not however the slightest mention of any obligation to 
 supply the vessel, but the trierarchs were only bound to launch 
 it (/ca^e\/cetv)**'^ The crew was appointed out of the demus, 
 but since a few only were obtained, and those inefficient, Apol- 
 lodorus was glad to hire some sailors of his own^^": he also 
 voluntarily paid them their wages, the generals having only 
 given him provision-money, and two months' pay out of seven- 
 teen^^ ^: he also subjected himself to many other voluntary 
 expenses, such as having fresh seamen in different places^ ^*: he 
 also equipped the vessel himself ^^^; nor was he single in this 
 respect, for others had likewise supplied the ship's furniture^ ^*, 
 and let it to their successors : other trierarchs however at this 
 period received their vessels ready equipped from the state; and 
 in the oration concerning the crown of the trierarchy^ ^% which 
 refers to the same form of this service, it is distinctly stated 
 that the state equipped the ship; and this is also evident from 
 the fact that in Olymp. 105, 4 (b.c. 35 7)^ ships' furniture which 
 had not been formerly paid for, was claimed from the trie- 
 rarchs^ '^ Apollodorus having supplied the furniture of his own 
 ship, had it in his power to demand of his successor to bring 
 new with him, or to purchase the old from himselP^^: with 
 regard to the ship itself there is nowhere any trace either of 
 selling or letting, but Apollodorus only requires of his successor 
 
 to both Thrasylochus and Meidias, the 
 latter of whom was only connected 
 with it as assistant to liis brother, and 
 had no share or partnership in the 
 trierarchy. Meidias was not trierarcli 
 before the introduction of these com- 
 panies, as we learn from Demosthenes, 
 p. 5G4. 
 
 =*«» P. 1207, 13. 
 
 ^'^ P. 1208. 
 3^' P. 1209. 
 3^^ P. 1210 sqq. 
 3^3 P. 1208, 17, p. 1217, 15. 
 31^ P. 1219, extr. 
 3'* P. 1229, 15. 
 
 3'® Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. p. 
 146. 
 3^7 C. Polycl. p. 1215.
 
 CH. XII.] 
 
 THE TRIERARCHY. 
 
 555 
 
 to receive it from him according to law, in order that he might 
 be at length relieved from his trierarchy, which he had already 
 performed beyond the legal time. 
 
 It is therefore hardly worth repeating that at that time 
 nothing but the repairing and preservation of the ship and ship's 
 fm'niture was required of the trierarchs by law, all other 
 expenses being merely voluntary; although these were by no 
 means trifling, as the state frequently furnished damaged ships, 
 and on voyages, and particularly in battles, great losses were 
 experienced. 
 
 This ApoUodorus, the son of Pasion, is a remarkable 
 instance how harshly a man could be treated, if he was rich and 
 ambitious, and moreover, like him, a new citizen : for his state- 
 ments bear the stamp of truth in a greater degree than the 
 assertion of Phormion, that ApoUodorus in the offices of trie- 
 rarch and choregus had not even expended as much from his 
 own property as was required of himself with an income of 20 
 minas^^^. Such extreme contradictions are to be found in the 
 same orator, provided that both speeches are the work of 
 Demosthenes. Others again performed their duties at less 
 expense, and only supplied what was absolutely necessary : and 
 even before the institution of the symmoriee, the trierarchs 
 began to let their trierarchy for a certain sum to a contractor, of 
 which Thrasylochus is the most ancient among the known 
 examples, in Olymp. 104, 1 (b.c. 364). Another instance 
 occurs in Olymp. 104, 4 (b.c. 361), of the same person again^^% 
 and about what amount was given at that time we have already 
 seen. It is evident that they transferred their trierarchy to 
 whoever required the lowest sum^^% a custom detrimental to 
 the state, not only on account of the insufficient performance 
 of the duties, but also because the contractors by their priva- 
 teering practices gave occasion to reprisals against the state^*\ 
 Upon occasions of defeat, the guilt therefore justly fell upon 
 those who had let their trierarchy, the letting being considered 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. pro Phorm. p. 956 sq. 
 319 Demosth. c. Polycl. p. 1222, 26. 
 
 32" Demosth. de Trierarch. Corona 
 p. 1230, 5. 
 
 3^1 Ibid. p. 1231 sq.
 
 556 
 
 FIRST AND SECOND FORMS OF 
 
 [bK. IVi 
 
 as a desertion of their post (XiTrord^covY^^, since the trierarch 
 was bound to be on board his ship and to command in 
 person. 
 
 Before we proceed further it may be worth mentioning, 
 that even after Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 358), the hull of the ship 
 was not supplied by the trierarchs or the symmorise, but that 
 the ships of war were in general the property of the public, as 
 Xenophon expressly says in his Essay upon the Revenues^**; 
 though I do not mean to deny that individual citizens occa- 
 sionally presented their triremes as a free gift to the state. 
 For since at these later times the trierarchy was often not 
 announced, and the trierarchs not appointed till the campaign 
 was already at hand^**, it was not possible that the trierarch 
 should build a new ship; if, however, it was expected from him 
 to buy one, a delay of this kind would have been most unwise, 
 as the possessors, in order to vex or defraud him, would have 
 been able (unless a maximum was fixed by the state) to demand 
 an exorbitant price; not to mention that of a sale of this 
 description, which must have occurred almost every year, there 
 is not the slightest trace in any ancient author. Or are we to 
 suppose that the person who had built a new ship, delivered it 
 to his successor gratis ? It is impossible to imagine that such 
 an inequality as this existed in the distribution of the burdens 
 of the trierarchy. To what purpose moreover had the Senate 
 of Five Hundred, together with the trireme-builders, the duty 
 of inspecting the ship-building^" ? To what purpose did the 
 latter receive their funds from the state, if the trierarchs 
 supplied their own ships ? To what purpose was it that about 
 Olymp. 106, 2 (b.c. 355), new triremes were built at the 
 expense of the state (as we see from the speech of Demosthenes 
 against Androtion), and that it was even enacted that the 
 senate should not receive its crown, if the ships were not in 
 readiness ? Do we not know that Eubulus superintended the 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. de Trierarch. Corona 
 p. 1230. 
 
 ^^^ Demoath. Philipp. i. p. 50, 10. 
 
 ^■"^^See book ii. ch. 19, comp. also ii. 
 ch. 6. That the building was paid for 
 by the public is particularly shown by 
 Demosth. c. Androt. p. 599, 13.
 
 CH. XII.] THE TRIERARCHY. 557 
 
 ship-building in the capacity of an officer of state^^^ 1 and that 
 Lycurgus provided 400 triremes, partly by repairing old, and 
 partly by providing new^^^ ? Still further ; in the proposal of 
 Demosthenes respecting the symmorise, the ships are supposed 
 to be already prepared, and together with the furniture were to 
 be assigned to the symmoriae by lot^*^ This proposal, how- 
 ever, only had in view a better regulation of the vessels 
 actually in the possession of the state. 
 
 There are only two passages which could seem to favour 
 the supposition that the state supplied the hull of the ship. 
 The first is where Ulpian asserts^ *° that the trierarch had at 
 times only supplied the ship; this, however, is an erroneous 
 conclusion from the oration against Meidias, in which it is 
 stated that at the institution of the symmoriae, the state 
 furnished the crew and equipment^'*'; whence he infers, and 
 with him the modern writers on the subject, that the trierarch s 
 supplied the ship. But as to this, what I have already 
 remarked upon the subject again applies, I do not consider it 
 necessary to bestow on it a particular examination. The 
 expression used by Isaeus'"', of an Athenian, might appear 
 more doubtful, "who did not make the ship {rrjv vavv iroLTjad- 
 fievos) by the assistance of a symmoria like the trierarchs of 
 the present day, but at his own expense ;'^ so that, according 
 to this passage, as well before as after the institution of the 
 symmoriie the trierarchs furnished the vessel. But the expres- 
 sion "to make a ship^^ must have another meaning in this 
 passage; because, as has been already shown, it is impossible 
 to suppose that the trierarchs supplied the hull of the ship 
 before the establishment of the symmoriae. Although to make 
 a ship may signify to build a new ship^^% it does not necessarily 
 
 3i6 Book"ii. cli. 7. | ^^^ Demosth. p. 564 extr. and p. oC5 
 
 3=^7 iii. 19. sup. 
 
 3=^« Demosth. p. 183 sup. (ha avy- \ ^^^ De Apollod. Hered. p. 184. 
 /cXr/pwo-ai (Tvyiiiopla (rco^droyv eKaaTj] ti)p \ ^'^'^ So in the speech against Audro- 
 nevreKaLbfKavatav. 1. 24, ra? rpL^peiS, \ tion, where rpi^peis TTOielaetu is the 
 
 as av CKaa-Toi Xap^cocrt, napeaKevaajxevas 
 Tvapex'^iv. 
 
 3=^9 Ad. Mid. p. 682 A. 
 
 same as Kaivas Tpn']peis TroielaSai, as 
 there the oi-ator is speaking of new 
 triremes ; and elsewhere.
 
 558 THE TRIERARCHY. C^K. IV. 
 
 bear that meaning; but the expression is general, and the 
 extent of its signification must be determined from the context. 
 Now the trierarch never received a ship actually ready for 
 sailing : the hull was given to him, and he then built upon it, 
 repaired what was damaged, supplied the furniture and decora- 
 tions^^^ and put the whole in perfect condition. This labour is 
 so considerable that I know no reason why it may not be 
 signified by the words ^Ho make a ship'' or "/o build a sMp^^^-'^ 
 for by these means the vessel is placed in a fit condition to sail. 
 Without, then, being hindered by this passage (which on 
 account of the indefinite nature of the expression, cannot be 
 considered as sufficient proof against us), we assert that the 
 state always furnished the pay and provision, in addition to 
 the empty vessel, and that all the alterations in the services of 
 the trierarchy, merely refer to the equipment of the vessel, and 
 to the method of levying the crews. 
 
 Chapter XIIL 
 
 Third Form of the Trierarchy. Syntelia and Symmori(B,from 
 Olymp. 105, 4 (b.c. 357) to the end of the I09th Olympiad 
 (B.C. 341). 
 
 From the account of Ulpian^^^, w^ho states that besides the two 
 trierarchs, sometimes three or even sixteen persons combined to 
 defray the expenses, it has been incorrectly supposed that this 
 must have been a peculiar kind of trierarchy, whereas Ulpian's 
 
 333 Cf. Thucyd. vi. 31. 
 
 ^^* It might with equal justice be 
 called vavTTTjyTja-aadat, in the sense of 
 a thorough repair and refitting, and 
 yet this expression is also applied to 
 new ships. Merely repairing is irria- 
 KevdC^iv, e g., in the decree in the 
 Lives of the Ten Orators, p. 278, and 
 Xenoph. Rep. Ath. 3, ci tis tt)v vavv 
 fxfj eVtcrKfva^ei, which is also to be 
 understood of trierarchs, i. e., these 
 words relate to the duties of the trie- 
 rarchs already appointed, and aftei-- 
 
 wards mention is made of the appoint- 
 ment of new trierarchs, and of their 
 lawsuits. Tr)v vavv with the article, 
 signifies a well-known and determinate 
 service, with regard to a fixed vessel, 
 which is assigned to an individual, and 
 shows that it relates to the trierarchs. 
 335 C. Mid. p. 681, G, p. C82, B. 
 The emendation of Petit, Koi ore 5e 
 €KKaideKa TpLrjpap)^ni, for 8e kcu 8eKa 
 rejected by Wolf, p. ciii. is evidently 
 correct.
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 
 
 559 
 
 words only mean that in the symmorise of the Twelve Hundred 
 sometimes three, sometimes sixteen, or any other number of 
 persons, managed the trierarchy of a ship^^*; it would be far 
 more consistent with his statement to refer these unions to the 
 symmorise ; a supposition which indeed can hardly be avoided, 
 as the symmorise were instituted immediately after the double 
 syntrierarchy, as will be presently shown ; and indeed at the 
 first establishment of the symmorise we find that two persons 
 held the trierarchy together, according to the ancient method, a 
 fact which we learn from the oration against Euergus and 
 Mnesibulus^^^ In the mean time, there is no proof that three 
 persons ever performed the trierarchy together: and it is 
 evident that Ulpian has merely fixed upon the latter number, in 
 order to explain how it was possible that Demosthenes should 
 have paid only 20 minas for a trierarchy, as he himself con- 
 sidered it certain that the lease of a trierarchy always cost a 
 talent ; notwithstanding that in the first place there could not 
 have been any fixed price, as it must have varied according to 
 the circumstances and expectations of the contractor ; and, 
 secondly, Demosthenes unquestionably performed the trierarchy 
 with one person only, and not with two^^^, and moreover long 
 before the introduction of the symmorise, viz. in Olymp. 
 104, 1 (B.C. 364). 
 
 The introduction of the symmorise is immediately connected 
 with the form of the trierarchy, which has been already treated 
 of, according to which this liturgy was borne either by one 
 alone or by two syntrierarchs. For in Olymp. 105, 3 (b.c. 
 358), it being found impossible to procure any or a sufficient 
 number of trierarchs according to the legal forms, it was con- 
 sidered necessary to summon voluntary trierarchs. As these, 
 however, could only suffice for the current year, it was 
 necessary to consider of some new regulation for the ensuing 
 
 3^^ P. 682, B, x^'^^oi yap Ka\ SiaKo- 
 (Tioi rjaav ol Tois rpiTjpapxtciis dcficopta- 
 pevoi. TOvTOiv 5e \ombv rj avveKKalbeKa 
 TTjv TpiTjpr] enX-qpovv fj crvvrpeiSf rj 
 6(roidT]noTe. The remainder of his 
 account is mixed with absurdities. 
 
 337 p. 1162 extr. cf. pp. 1148—1154, 
 in reference to the connection of the 
 fact and the time. 
 
 ^^^ See above chap. 12, and particu- 
 larly note 308.
 
 560 
 
 THIRD FORM OF TRlERARCHY. 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 year, and as it was impossible to provide for the public service 
 according to the actual system, they agreed to appoint 1200 
 partners {avvreXeLs) distributed into symmorise, who were to 
 perform the duties of the trierarchy. In the case to which the 
 oration against Euergus and Mnesibulus refers, the trierarchs 
 had been already regulated according to the symmoriee; the 
 trierarchy, however, of the person for whom this speech was 
 written, which was performed after the establishment of the 
 symmorise, took place in the archonship of Agathocles, Olymp. 
 105, 4 (B.C. 357)'"'. Yet even at that time, two persons were 
 sometimes appointed trierarchs out of the symmorise, in order 
 to perform their duties in person. In earlier times no trace of 
 symmoriee exists, but of the syntrierarchy alone. It is, there- 
 fore, highly probable that this year was the first in which the 
 symmoriee came into operation. In the oration of Isseus con- 
 cerning the inheritance of Apollodorus'", the date of which 
 might be placed further back, but cannot be brought lower 
 down, in the oration against Leptines^"^, which was delivered in 
 
 3=^9 Demosth. c. Euerg. et IMnesib. 
 p. 1152, 18, cf. Petit. Leg. Att. iii. 
 4, 10. Concerning the syntrierarchs, 
 see p. 1162, extr. The expenses 
 wliich were then entailed upon the 
 pei-son for whom this speech is written, 
 by his syntrierarchy, were so great 
 that he consumed the money appointed 
 for the fine to be paid to his adversary, 
 amounting to 13 minas and over, p. 
 1154. I must in this place explain 
 away a passage from which it might 
 appear that sjTnmorise Avere in exist- 
 ence before Olymp. 105, 4. It is the 
 passage quoted above on the subject 
 of the trierarchy, in the oration against 
 Euergus and Mnesib. p. 1145, 21. 
 ATjixo)(^dpT]s de 6 Ilaiavuvs fV ttj (Tvymo- 
 pia a>v Koi ocfxiXav rfj TTo'Xet (tk€vt) fiera 
 06o^i7/iou TOVTOv, crvvrpiy'ipap^os yevo' 
 fxfvos. It has been already remarked, 
 that the syntrierarchy of these two ' 
 persons must have *^ taken place in 
 Olymp. 105, 2 or 3. Now Demochares | 
 was a member of the symmoriffi in 
 
 Olymp. 105, 4, and he may thus appear 
 to have served the former syntrierar- 
 chy in the symmorise, which, if it 
 were true, would give an earlier date 
 to the symmorire. But wliat prevents 
 us from supposing that Demochares 
 was syntrierarch before, and did not 
 belong to the symmoriae until Olymp. 
 105,4? What renders this the more 
 probable is, that he alone is stated to 
 have been in the symmoriai, while 
 Theophemus is not mentioned as a 
 member of one, and if they had both 
 been members of a symmorise when 
 they peiformed that trierarchy, Theo- 
 phemus must have been in the same 
 symmoriae as Demochares; whereas 
 the contrary must be inferred from 
 the words of the orator. 
 
 S'lo P. 1{;4, comp. Wolf, p. cix. who 
 supposes tlie speech to belong to the 
 105th 01}^npiad. If it was not deli- 
 vered in Oljnnp. 105, 4, its date is 
 Olymp. 100. 
 
 ■^■'' § 19, p. 403, 24.
 
 CH. XIII.] SYNTELI^ AND SYMMORI/E. 561 
 
 Olymp. 106, 2 (b.c. 355), in the oration upon the symmoriae 
 which was spoken in Olymp. 106, 3 (b.c. 354), and in the 
 oration against Meidias, which belongs to Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 
 353), this institution is recognised as existing. The law of 
 Periander, by which, according to the account contained in the 
 oration against Euergus and Mnesibulus^^*, the symmoriae of 
 the trierarchy were introduced, was evidently, as may be seen 
 from its agreement with what has been stated, the primary and 
 original enactment upon this subject. 
 
 The 1200 Partners (o-uz^reXet?)''' were properly the most 
 wealthy individuals according to the valuation, and among 
 these, as was the case in the symmoriae of the property taxes, 
 there was a separate body of three hundred, which was still in 
 existence when Demosthenes abolished the symmoriae^^*; the 
 whole number was divided into twenty symmoriae or classes^"*: in 
 these classes a number of members combined for the equip- 
 ment of a ship, which body was called a Synteleia {avvTe\€tay*\ 
 A body of this kind often consisted of five or six persons^''^, so 
 that a symmoria could furnish ten or twelve ships; but there 
 were fifteen persons to each ship, and therefore only four ships 
 were provided by a symmoria of sixty persons. A division of 
 this kind, which, according to Hyperides"*^, was itself called a 
 symmoria, was at certain times appointed by law: the most 
 singular fact however is, that before Demosthenes introduced 
 the new law of the trierarchy according to the valuation, vv^hen 
 the institution of the symmoriae was still in existence^"", 
 according to the actual law sixteen persons were appointed out 
 of the syntelias for each ship, for twenty-five or thirty years"", 
 
 ^*- P. 1 145. j tines as above, Harpocrat. and Etymol. 
 
 ^*^ Demosth. c. jNIid. p. 564, extr. I in v. crvvreXe^s. 
 de Symmor. p. 182, 19, and the gram- \ '^^ Hyperides ap. Harpocrat. in v. 
 
 marians passim, Harpocration, Suidas, 
 Photius, Lex. Seg. pp. 238, 300, also p. 
 192, 3, which latter article is however 
 very incorrect. 
 
 ^** Dinarch. c. Demosth. p. 33 ; 
 comp below, ch. 14. 
 
 »^* Demosth. de Symmor. p. 182, 19. 
 
 ^*^ Concerning tins word see De- 
 mosthenes against Meidias and Lep- 
 
 avfifiopia, corrupted by Petit iii. 4, J. 
 
 3^8 Ibid. 
 
 ^■*^ This is evident from the speech 
 for the Crown, p. 329, 17, p. 260, 21. 
 
 ^^'^ Law in Demosth. pro Corona, p. 
 261, extr. Karakoyos. Tovs Tpiijpdp' 
 ;^ovy /caXetcr^ai eVt ti)i> Tpirjpi] avvcKKai-' 
 dcKa €K Twv iv Tols \6xoLS (TvvTiKetiov 
 dno f'Uoa-i Kal nevre iroyv fU reTTapd- 
 2 o
 
 562 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 and these sixteen bore the burden in equal shares. Since this 
 number does not agree with the constitution of the twenty sym- 
 mori^e of sixty persons each^ we must either suppose an entire 
 change in the internal arrangements of the 1200 Partners, w^hich 
 is by no means probable; or an increase in their number to 
 1280; or, if neither of these conjectures appears probable, dis- 
 cover some other method of explanation. Might w^e not assume, 
 since a part only of the law has come down to us, that there 
 were other material additions to it, which made the meaning 
 clear? It is possible that the syntelias did not consist only of 
 fifteen persons, as they are stated by Hyperides (although he 
 calls them symmorise), and that to these fifteen another mem- 
 ber was purposely added from a different syntelia, in order to 
 prevent any unjust proceeding among the other fifteen members, 
 and to perform the duties of a comptroller over them. The 
 superintendence of the whole business was performed by the 
 most wealthy, upon whom the burdens of the trierarchy chiefly 
 fell, that is to say, the leaders of the symmorise {rjyefioves rcov 
 o-vfi/jLopLMV )"^ and the managers of the symmoriae {eTrifie- 
 XrjTal TMV av/jL/JLopLcovY^'^. 
 
 KovTu, eVi 'laov rfj X'^PV'/^^ ;;^pco/xe'vov?. confused and unsatisfactory. Hiero 
 Cf. p. 260, 27, p. 261, 3, 16. XopTj-yLa , nymus Wolf is of opinion that farther 
 here means any public service in the researches are necessary as to the 
 general sense. But the difficulty in meaning of the ttoXltikoI and rpi-qpap- 
 the expression eV rots' \6xoi.^ cannot be x'-'^^'- ^oxoi, and considers that Demos- 
 solved, nor has F. A. Wolf, p. 112, thenes uses this expression for the 
 been able to remove it. It is certain symmoria?, which is the only method 
 that \6xos may mean a civil as well as of overcoming the difficulty. I may 
 a military division, and if net from likewise mention, that at that time, as 
 Xenophon (Hieron. 9, 5), where it is seen from note 349, the symmoriae 
 may be referred to a military division, , were actually in existence, and the 
 it is evident from Aristotle (Polit. v. only reason why in Demosth. adv. 
 8) : Tov ixeu ovv fxi) KXeTVTeadaL to. koivo. Bceot. de Xom. p. 997, 1, about Olymp. 
 77 TTapdboaLs yiyveadoi rcov xPW^'^^'^ 1^7, 1, the trierarch is opposed to the 
 TrapovTUiv rravTcov roiv noXiTcovy kol symmorije, is that the sjTnmorige of 
 dvTiypa<pa Kara (pparpias kgi Xoxovs Kai the property taxes were looked upon 
 (bvXcis Tideadcocrav. The lochitse also as the more ancient and important, 
 occui- in Eustathius in a passage where although there were at that time sym- 
 the context is of a similar nature. See i moriae of the trierarchy. 
 the passage quoted by F. A. Wolf i ^51 Demosth. de Corona, p. 329, 17, 
 from Salmasius, :Misc. Defens. p. Sal- 1 p. 260, 21. 
 
 mas. ad I. A. et R. p. 135, where how- 2^2 Qrat. c. Euerg. et :Mnesib. p. 
 ever the information given is extremely j 1145, 15, p. 1146, 10.
 
 CH. XIII.] SYNTELI.E AND SYMMORIiE. 563 
 
 In treating df the amount of the services required, we may- 
 pass over the passages concerning the hull, and the pay and 
 provision, which have been already examined; with regard 
 however to the equipment and the levying of the crew we find 
 the most satisfactory accounts. For even before the introduc- 
 tion of the symmorise, the state provided the ship^s furniture, 
 although some trierarchs supplied it at their own cost^"; 
 whence it happened that in Olymp. 105, 4 (b.c. 358) there was 
 none in the storehouse, the old ship^s furniture not having been 
 paid for by the former trierarchs; and even in the Piraeus 
 there were neither sails nor tackling to be bought in sufficient 
 quantities; therefore by a decree of Cheeredemus the payment 
 of the money due was required, and the names of the debtors 
 were delivered in by the overseers of the docks to the leaders 
 of the synnnoriae, and to the trierarchs whose ships were then 
 about to saiP^\ By the law of Periander it had been enacted 
 that the leaders of the symmorise should receive the names of 
 those who were indebted for the ship^s furniture, and distribute 
 among the several trierarchs the duty of enforcing the restitu- 
 tion of it for their own use. The names of the debtors were 
 engraven upon tablets, and all disputes arising between the 
 parties were brought before the court of justice by the officers 
 whose duty it was to dismiss the fleet (aTrocrroXet?) and by the 
 overseers of the docks. Any person who had received ship^s 
 furniture was obliged to deliver it up according to the inven- 
 tory [Stdypa/jL/jLa rcov aKevoov), either at Athens, or to his 
 successor who was sent from the symmoria^". At this time 
 any person's property could be confiscated, if he did not sur- 
 render the ship's furniture, or transfer his own by sale to his 
 successor, who probably had power to distrain the property of 
 the former. From all these circumstances, which are stated in 
 the oration against Euergus and Mnesibulus^^% it is evident 
 that the vessels were equipped for the symmoriee by the state. 
 
 353 
 
 Orat. c. Euerg. et Mnesib. p. absurd 
 
 ^^^ Concerning this expression see 
 Lex. Seg. p. 236. 
 
 1146. 
 
 ^^* ToLS Tpiripapxois Toi^ eKTrXeovai 
 t6t€. Reiske's ovk eWXeovo-i is highly ' ^*® Pp. 1145— 1152. 
 
 2 o 2
 
 564 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 In the same manner Demosthenes, in his speech concerning 
 the symmorise"^, proposes that the money still owing for 
 ship's furniture should be collected according to the inventory 
 belonging to the great symmoriae; that these classes should dis- 
 tribute the money thus received among their several divisions, 
 which should then send out the ships ready equipped. We 
 learn from the same orator, in the speech against Meidias^'% 
 that the state furnished the crew and equipment of the vessel to 
 the syntelias. 
 
 The trierarch therefore had only to take care that the vessel, 
 with all its appurtenances, was in proper repair and order as he 
 received it. Yet the trierarchs withdrew themselves even from 
 this duty; for the most wealthy, who were to perform the ser- 
 vice for their syntelia, let their trierarchy to a contractor for a 
 talent, and received the whole sum from their colleagues; so 
 that many in reality paid nothing, and yet were exempted by the 
 trierarchy from all other liturgies^ *^ Why the leases should 
 have been higher in more recent than in earlier times, when the 
 services required of the trierarchs had been increased, may 
 appear singular; but of this more will be said presently. 
 
 The irregularities which soon prevailed in the symmoriae 
 appear to have prevented them from attaining their end. On 
 this account Demosthenes®^" in Olymp. 106, 3 (b.c. 354), made 
 a proposal to improve the constitution of the symmoriae: the 
 essential points of which plan are as follows. Instead of 1200 
 he proposed to take 2000 persons, in order that, subtracting 
 all who had any possible ground of exemption, there would 
 remain without fail 1200. These were, as before, to be distri- 
 buted into twenty symmoriee of sixty members, and each again 
 into five divisions of twelve persons, every person being suc- 
 ceeded by another less rich than himself; and upon the whole 
 there were to be 100 small symmoriee^^\ The number of tri- 
 remes was to be 300, in twenty divisions, each of fifteen ships; 
 so that of each hundred, either the first, the second, or the third 
 
 *•'•' P. 183, 17 sqq. ! Corona, pp. 2f;0— 162. 
 
 3*« P. 5b'4 extr. p. 566 Piip. | ■'"^" De 8yminor. p. 182 sqq. 
 
 ?*" Demosth. c. Mid. tibi sup. cf. de ^' Cf. Phot, in v. vavKpapia,
 
 CH. XIII.] SYNTELI^ AND SYMMORl^. 565 
 
 (so called because they were to be successively summoned at 
 different times), each great symmoria was to receive five^ each 
 small symmoria one ship. Upon the whole each great was to 
 have fifteen and each small symmoria three ships. Moreover 
 the whole valuation of the country, amounting to 6000 talents, 
 was, '^ in order that the money also should be well regulated/' 
 to be divided into one hundred parts, each of 60 talents, of 
 which five parts would come to each large, and one to each 
 small symmoria, in order that if 100 triremes were required, 
 there should be 60 talents of the valuation to supply the 
 expenses, and that there should be twelve trierarchs to a ship. 
 If however there were 200 triremes, he proposed that there 
 should be allotted to each vessel 30 talents and six trierarchs; 
 and if there were 300, that 20 talents should be given to meet 
 the expenses, and that there should be four trierarchs. 
 
 Here is a difficulty with reference to the valuation, which 
 has been passed over by most of the commentators, and which 
 can only be explained in the following manner. Since 6000 
 talents were the valuation of the whole country and of all the 
 citizens whose property was valued (and not only of the Twelve 
 Hundred, as Budseus assumes in his interpretation of this pas- 
 sage) ^^*, and as in the symraoriee of the trierarchy there were in 
 reality only twelve hundred, the division of the valuation among 
 the symmorise cannot have been made for the expenses of the 
 trierarchy, but only for that which the state supplied for the 
 equipment of the fleet, and the maintenance and pay of the 
 crew. The orator also, if the 6000 talents had been the taxable 
 capital of the Twelve Hundred, must necessarily have spoken of 
 it more distinctly, when he mentions the manner in which they 
 were distributed: he would doubtless have said, that they were 
 to be so divided that each of the symmorise was to receive an 
 equal sum of money; that is to say, each of the small sym- 
 morise 60 talents; although the arrangement could not have 
 been made precisely in this manner. Consequently the orator 
 only sketches out a plan for the distribution of the property 
 taxes according to the valuation, parallel to the symmorise of 
 
 »«- De asse et partibus ejus, v. p. 534 sqq. Comp. above chap. 9.
 
 566 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 the trierarchy, in order that out of the part of the valuation 
 which belonged to each symmoria of the trierarchy all the 
 expenses should be defrayed which the trierarchs did not 
 undergo; a proposal by which the system of naval affairs was 
 first firmly organized, since there was so frequently a defi- 
 ciency of pay and provision, and of the other articles which were 
 furnished by the state. 
 
 Moreover the public equipment was to be furnished to the 
 symmoriee, according to the same proportion, at the public 
 cost. The generals were also to divide the docks into ten 
 parts, in order that ships' stations to the number of thirty 
 should be situated near to one another ; that each part should 
 be assigned to a tribe or two symmoriee of sixty members, with 
 thirty ships, and a trierarch be appointed to each ship. The 
 place which each tribe received by lot was to be further divided 
 in the same manner among its third part {rpcTTus)^ so that each 
 should receive ten ships. The levying of the crews was to be 
 effected in the same manner. 
 
 Whether these good counsels were ever put into execution 
 we are not informed, but we know that this liturgy continued 
 to decline until Demosthenes passed the law concerning the 
 trierarchy according to the valuation, as he saw that naval 
 affairs, particularly with regard to the companies of sixteen, 
 were totally mismanaged ; that the rich exempted themselves 
 from the moderate contribution which was required; that the 
 property of the middling or poorer classes was gradually sacri- 
 ficed, as they contributed an equal sum with the wealthier, 
 without any distinction of property; and, finally, that the pre- 
 parations were never ready at the right time, and the state lost 
 its opportunity^^ ^ 
 
 3^ Demostli. de Corona, p. 260. The j the trierarchy. But, in the first place, 
 expression areXels dno fiiKpav dvaXco- the words conti'adict one another ; for 
 fxaTiov admits of a two-fold explana- ' if these persons contributed small sums 
 tion. In the first place it might mean they were not entirely free ; also it 
 that they had obtained an immunity would have been necessary to mention 
 by means of small payments, as by this the burden from which they exempted 
 small contribution to the trierarchy i themselves, and 5ta would have been 
 
 better than dno : I therefore under- 
 stand the words thxis : " they exempted 
 
 they were exempted from liturgies 
 during the time that they were serving
 
 CH. XIII.] 
 
 SYXTELI/E AND SYMMORl^. 
 
 567 
 
 This last consequence of mismanagement is censured by 
 Demosthenes as early as in Olymp. 107, 1 (b.c. 852)''*, and it 
 was partly to this reason, and partly to the exhaustion of their 
 strength, that a fresh necessity for the existence of voluntary 
 trierarchs was owing. The first voluntary trierarchy (eVtSoo-t?) 
 has been already noticed, the second was used for the fleet 
 against Olynthus'", and the third for the war in Euboea, in 
 which the Athenian army at Tamynee was supposed to have 
 been surrounded, which account, as was afterwards shown, only 
 originated in a stratagem of Phocion; at that time some citizens 
 made free gifts of triremes''^ perhaps together with the hull; 
 although it is possible that to make a free gift of a trireme 
 {rpLrjpT) eTTiSouvat) only means to equip a public trireme lying 
 in the docks, and to manage it at the individuals expense. 
 
 This third voluntary trierarchy occurred immediately before 
 the time when Demosthenes was insulted by Meidias at the 
 Dionysia, and composed the speech against that individuaP^^. 
 Now Demosthenes, according to the correct view of Corsini, 
 was born in Olymp. 98, 4 (b.c. 385), and not, as Dionysius 
 supposes, in Olymp. 99, 4 (b.c. 381), and when he wrote the 
 oration against Meidias was thirty-two years old'^% which there- 
 fore falls in Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353) '^^ and not, as Dionysius 
 
 themselves from the expense, which 
 was proportionally small for their pro- 
 perty ;" for, as has been already shown, 
 the whole expenses were often de- 
 frayed by their colleagues, and they 
 themselves contributed nothing. The 
 common expression is indeed dreXrjs 
 TLvos, but in an unusual phrase like 
 the present, with the addition of the 
 words fxiKpcbv civaXoifxaTOiv the orator 
 might have added diro for the sake of 
 distinctness. [The first of these two 
 explanations is preferred by Schsefer, 
 Apparatus ad Demosthenem, vol. ii. 
 p. 153.— Transl.] 
 
 "^^ Philipp. i. p. 50. 
 
 se-^ Demosth. c. Mid. p. 5G6. 
 
 ^^« Demosth. c. Mid. pp. 566— 5G8. 
 
 ^f' P. 566, 28, where observe vvv, 
 and p. 567, 16. 
 
 =^^8 P. 564, 19. 
 
 ^^^ See Wolf, p. cviii. cf. p. Lxii. 
 Petit iii. 4, 7, with less accuracy as- 
 sumes Olymp. 106, 3, not reckoning 
 the thirty-two years complete. My 
 statement may be also supported 
 against that of Dionysius by the tes- 
 timony of Demosthenes against Mei- 
 dias, p. 541, Demosthenes, after the 
 suit against his guardians, had brought 
 an action against Meidias for libellous 
 words {diK-q KaKTjyopias), on account of 
 the insult which Meidias had offered 
 to him at the very time when the 
 cause against Aphobus was to have 
 been brought before the court. Mei- 
 dias was condemned in contumaciam 
 (elXov eprjfjLrjv, says Demosthenes); af- 
 terwards however, as he did not pay 
 his fine, Demosthenes brought against
 
 568 
 
 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 thinks, in Olymp. 10/; 4 (b.c. 349), and the Euboean war in 
 like manner in Olymp. 106, 4 (b.c. 353), or a short time before, 
 since some interval had elapsed between the offence and the 
 composition of the speech, as several passages of the oration 
 show, and must necessarily be the case from the course of 
 judicial proceedings. I remark besides, that the battle of 
 Tamynee''", and other events connected with the Euboean 
 expedition, have nothing to do with the expedition against 
 Euboea in Olymp. 109, 4 (b.c. 341), with which it may be 
 easily confounded. Plutarch of Eretria had caUed upon the 
 Athenians for assistance^'', and having a party in Athens, to 
 which moreover Meidias belonged^'*, he was supported against 
 the advice of Demosthenes, (who, in the oration concerning 
 Peace, delivered in Olymp. 108,3, b.c. 346''% boasts of having 
 
 him an actio rei judicatce {biKq e^ovXrjs) 
 eight years before the npo^oXr) against 
 Meidias on account of the insult at the 
 Dionysia. One cannot however well 
 reckon that so many years intei-\'ened 
 between the action against Apliobus 
 and the institution of the diKrj e^ovXrjs, 
 as to make the latter fall in Olymp. 
 105, 4; it would be more conveniently 
 placed in Olymp. 104, 4 j according to 
 which supposition the oration against 
 Meidias was written in Olymp. lOG, 4. 
 Taylor (Fvsef. ad Mid.) and Wolf (p. 
 c^•iii.) are indeed of opinion that events 
 are mentioned in the oration against 
 Meidias which happened later; but 
 there can be no doubt that none but 
 the expeditions already mentioned are 
 alluded to, which are evidently of ear- 
 lier date, and have been confounded 
 with the subsequent wars, the Olyn- 
 thian expedition even having been 
 mistaken by Ulpian ad p. 578, Reisk. 
 Upon the whole there is no reason for 
 supposing that Demosthenes wrote the 
 speech against Meidias a considerable 
 time after the event itself took place ; 
 on the contraiy, it may be distinctly 
 shown, for which at present 1 have no 
 room, that the speech was written soon 
 
 after the 7rpo/3oX^, and before the com- 
 position with Meidias, for which reason 
 it was left by him unfinished. [See 
 Clinton's Fast. Hellen. vol. ii. App. 
 c. 20, ed. 3.— Transl.] 
 
 370 ^schin. de Fals. Leg. p. 332 
 sqq. (delivered in Olymp. 109, 2,) and 
 c. Ctesiph. p. 480 sqq. Plutarch, Phoc. 
 1 2, 13, is most explicit upon this point ; 
 the date however cannot be deter- 
 mined from his account, as the events 
 that follow are narrated very briefly : 
 I only remark that the dismission of 
 Chares to the Hellespont, mentioned 
 in the Life of Phocion, chap. 16, must 
 not, for the purpose of reconciling it 
 with my account, be referred to that 
 which took place in Olymp. lOu, 4 
 (Diod.xvi. 34), but the historian passes 
 over to occurrences of far later date ; 
 of which elsewhere. Of the passage 
 in the speech agamst Bceotus de Nom. 
 p. 999, with regard to the battle of 
 Tamynse, I have already treated in 
 note 194. 
 
 -7' ^schin. p. 480, Plutarch, ubi 
 i sup. 
 
 "7* Demosth. c. :Mid. p. 579, 2, cf. 
 p. 650, extr. 
 
 =^7 P. 58, 3.
 
 CH. XIII.] SYNTELI^ AND SYMMORI^E. 569 
 
 Opposed him,) and Phocion being sent as general was successful 
 in the battle against the mercenaries of Philip and those from 
 Phocis. Subsequently Plutarch the Eretrian was himself again 
 driven out by Phocion^^^ for having in conjunction with Hege- 
 silaus the Athenian deceived the people, and stimulated Eubcea 
 to revolt; on which account Hegesilaus was brought before a 
 court of justice^^'*; the free constitution of Euboea was re-esta- 
 blished; and the people were for a time their own masters, 
 until dissensions arose, which ended with the setting up of three 
 tyrants favoured by Philip; Hipparchus, Automedon, and Clei- 
 tarchus, and also of Philistides in Oreus, as Demosthenes^"* 
 relates in the third Philippic, which was spoken in Olymp. 
 109, 3 (B.C. 340); these same tyrants were however finally 
 driven out by the Athenians, at the persuasion of Demos- 
 thenes^'", and Cleitarchus was slain by Phocion in Olymp. 
 109,4 (B.C. 341)'^^ So much with regard to the Euboean 
 expedition. 
 
 With reference to the second voluntary trierarchy, for the 
 expedition against Olynthus, it will be seen that it did not occur 
 long before the third; for the war of Olynthus was still going on 
 at the conclusion of the Euboean war, as the cavalry which had 
 served at Euboea went from thence immediately to Olynthus^^". 
 
 374 Plutarch, in Phoc. j 16, p. 324, 16. Concerning Philistides 
 
 375 Demosth. cie Fuls. Leg. p. 434, see Demosth. Pliilip. iii. p. 119, 22, 
 14, and there Ulpian p. 390 D. To i p. 126, 3 sqq. de Corona p. 248, 15, 
 this war the passage in Orat. adv. : p. 252, 17 sqq. 
 
 Neter. p. 1346, 14, refers. Schneider ' ^77 Demosth. de Corona p. 252. 
 ad Xenoph. de Yectig. p- 151, con- ^78 j)Iq^ xvi. 74. Wesseling, in 
 founds with it the war of Olymp. 105, his note upon this passage, was aware 
 3, concerning which see above chap. 12, of the difference between the two bat- 
 and particularly the passages in note | ties won by Phocion, but he himself, 
 293. The passage there quoted from : as well as the commentators upon Plu- 
 tke speech for the Alegalopolitans, tarch, are in error, when they propose 
 which was delivered in Olymp. 106, 4, to write KXeirapxov for UXovTapxov 
 might indeed be refen-ed to the war of in Phoc. 13, not to mention others, 
 the latter year; the oration however i who confound the totally different 
 appears to have been spoken before accounts respecting Plutarch and Clei- 
 the beginning of the war, otherwise tarchus. 
 
 more mention would undoubtedly have ' ^^9 Demosth. c. Mid. p. 578 sup. Cf. 
 been made of it. 1 Orat. c. Neaer. ubi sup. 
 
 376 See p. 125, cf. de Corona p. 248, ,
 
 570 
 
 THIRD FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 We cannot therefore understand the auxiliary troops which 
 Athens furnished to the Olynthians against Philip in Olymp. 
 107j 4 (B.C. 349), although a body of cavalry was also sent 
 from Athens on that occasion^^"; nor can the war of Timotheus 
 against Olynthus be meant^^', which this general still carried on 
 with the assistance of the Macedonians^^', and which must thus 
 occur even before the first voluntary trierarchy (Olymp. 105, 3, 
 B.C. 358), probably in Olymp. 104, 1 (b.c. 364), when Timo- 
 theus took Torone and Potidsea^^^ cities which were of the 
 greatest importance to the Olynthians^ ^*. This expedition more 
 probably belongs to the times subsequent to Olymp. 105, 3 
 (B.C. 358), in which year Philip made an alliance with the 
 Olynthians, and gave them Pydna, with the promise of Potidaea 
 as welP^^; Athens and Olynthus were afterwards engaged in 
 hostilities^^^ for which in the 106th Olympiad the second volun- 
 tary trierarchy was doubtless necessary, after the Athenians had 
 exhausted themselves with the Social war. 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 
 The Fourth Form of the Trierarchy. Trierarchy according to 
 the Valuation, as prescribed by the Law of Demosthenes^ 
 after Olymp, 110, i (b.c. 339). 
 
 Demosthenes, being well aware of the defects in the constitu- 
 tion of the symmorise, at the time when he held the office of 
 manager of naval affairs {iTnardrrj^ rev vavrtKov), brought for- 
 ward in a new law an improved and rational constitution of the 
 trierarchy, having rejected the bribes which the leaders and 
 other wealthy members of the symmorise offered him, and with- 
 stood the action for illegal proceedings (ypa(f>r) Trapavoficov) 
 which Patroclus of Phlya had brought against him^^^ 
 
 ^" Philochorus ap. Dlonys. Halicar- 
 nass. vol. ii. p. 123, ed. Sylb. 
 
 ^^' Concerning the latter person see 
 book ii. cli. 24. 
 
 ^^^ Deniostli. Olynth. ii. p. 22, sup. 
 
 ^«^ Diod. XV. «]. 
 
 ^^* Diod. xvi. 8. 
 
 3«5 Diod. ibid. 
 
 ^^^ Libauiiis Argum. ad Demosth. 
 Olynth. 1. 
 
 ^^ Demosth. de Corona, pp. 260, 
 261. Concerning the office which De-
 
 CH. XIV.] FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 571 
 
 The symmoriee and syntelice then in existence, the members 
 of which had even given up the names of trierarchs, and called 
 themselves partners or sharers (avvreXeh), were abolished, and 
 the services were again brought back to the valuation. The 
 trierarchs were, according to the words of the law, rated for a 
 trireme according to their property as stated in the register, in 
 such a manner that one trireme was required from 10 talents; 
 whoever was valued at a higher sum was, according to the same 
 proportion, returned to the trierarchy as being bound to furnish 
 three triremes and one auxiliary vessel {uTrrjperiKov) ; while all 
 those who had less than 10 talents were to unite in syntelias 
 until they made up that sum^^^ The terms of the law, although 
 towards the end they are not expressed with precision, distinctly 
 show that the 10 talents were not merely property, but the 
 property according to the valuation, or the taxable capital, as 
 Budaeus before understood it^^^ Thus if the valuation of the 
 year of Nausinicus was still in force, which was the foundation 
 of the proposals made in the speech concerning the symmorise 
 in Olymp. 106, 3 (b.c. 354), whoever was possessed of 50 
 talents was obliged to pro\dde one trireme; of 150 talents and 
 over, as in the case of Diphilus, was to supply three triremes, 
 and, to preserve the proportion, an auxiliary vessel besides: for 
 the sake however of preventing the burden from being too 
 oppressive, this was the highest rate 6ven for the most w^ealthy; 
 so that if a person was possessed of 500 talents, the number 
 
 mosthenes held when he put his pro- 
 ject into execution, see ^sch. c. Cte- 
 siph. p. 614. The law first came be- 
 fore the senate, who referred it to the 
 
 ovoiv T} ovaia a7T0T€TifjiTjfj.eur} fj )(^pr]fj.aTa>v, 
 Kara tov avaXoyKTfxbv ecoy TpicovrrXoiav 
 Koi vTTTjpeTLKOv T) XeLTOvpyla e(TT(0' Kara 
 TTjv avTTjv 8e avaXoy'iav earo) koi ols 
 
 people. Instead of eiarjveyKe vofiov eXdrTcov ovcrla earl twv deKa laXavTcop 
 els TO rpi-qpapxi-K-OV in the speech for the eiff avvreXeuiv (Tvvayop.4vois els ra dcKa 
 Ci own, should be read, elarjveyKe v6p.oi> Tokavra. On account of an observa- 
 rpiTjpapxiKov ; which I mention in order tion of the last editor, I may mention 
 that it may not be supposed that there ' that the ancient form is rpirjpapxos 
 existed a separate office called to Tpir)- ; and yvfxvaaiapxos, and not Tpirjpdpxijs, 
 papxiKov. ' yvfxvaaidpxf]S, as is proved by inscrip- 
 
 ^^^ Demosth. ibid. p. 262, sup. Ka- | tions, for example, Corp. Inscript. Nos. 
 ToXoyos. Tovs Tpirjpdpxovs alpeladai ! 147 and 158. 
 enl TYjv TpLr)pr] dno ttjs ovcrias koto. tI- ^^^ Ubi sup. p. 543. 
 jXTjaiVj OTTO TaXdvTiov beKa' iav be rrXet- \
 
 572 FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 which he was bound to furnish was the same: all who were 
 possessed of an inconsiderable property contributed according 
 to their valuation, and diminished in a corresponding ratio to 
 the diminution in their property. 
 
 By this law a great alteration was effected. All persons 
 paying taxes were rated under the new regulations; while the 
 poor, who had been very much oppressed during the time of the 
 Twelve Hundred, received some relief, which was the intention 
 of Demosthenes^®"; and those who formerly contributed a six- 
 teenth to the trierarchy of one vessel, were now trierarchs of 
 two^®'; that is to say, if their taxable capital amounted to 20 
 talents. Of persons whose valuation was still higher than this 
 sum Demosthenes says not a word, and it would almost appear 
 as if no higher valuations had been then in existence, although 
 they are allowed for in the law; and if the statements of the 
 property were correctly made, there must have been some of a 
 higher amount. 
 
 The consequences were, according to Demosthenes, highly 
 beneficial; during the whole war, which was carried on under 
 the regulations of the new law, no trierarch threw himself on 
 the protection of the people, or took refuge at the altar of Diana 
 of Munychia, or was thrown into prison; no trireme was lost 
 to the state, or remained lying in the docks, from there being no 
 means to send her out to sea, which had formerly been the case, 
 as the poor were unable to perform the necessary services. 
 
 What portion of the expense the trierarch was forced to 
 sustain, we are not informed; probably the same as under the 
 symmorise: and if the distribution was really made as the law 
 directed, and the trierarchy was performed in turn through the 
 whole valuation, \nthout ever falling a second time upon the 
 same person, however rich, it could not have been oppressive. 
 If we reckon that, as formerly, it cost about a talent, the total 
 expense of the trierarchs for 100, 200, or 300 triremes amounted 
 to an equal number of talents, or a sixtieth, a thirtieth, and a 
 twentieth of the valuation; that is to say, for the first class one- 
 third, two-thirds, and one per cent, of their property; for the 
 
 ''s" De Corona, pp. 260—262. 39' Ibid. p. 261.
 
 CH. XIV.] FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 
 
 573 
 
 poorer a proportionally less amount: and of the annual incomes, 
 if they are only taken as a tenth part of the property, 3^, 6f, 
 and 10 per cent, for the most wealthy. But we may reckon that 
 at that time Athens had not more than between 100 and 200 
 triremes at sea; at least the occasions on which there were 300 
 must have been extremely rare, although the orators in exao-- 
 geration speak of that number: so that this war-tax did not for 
 the richest class amount on an average to more than one-third 
 and two-thirds per cent, of their property. 
 
 The arrangement of Demosthenes was upon this occasion, 
 as in his former proposal concerning the constitution of the 
 symmorise, calculated for 300 triremes^^^; and for this number 
 300 trierarchs serving in person must have been necessary. 
 The chief burden therefore naturally fell upon the leaders of 
 the former symmorise, and upon the second and third symmo- 
 rites who were next in order (of whom Demosthenes says that 
 they would have been glad to have given him large sums of 
 money in order to prevent the passing of the law^^^), or upon 
 the Three Hundred, according to an earlier form of trierarchy, 
 as is proved by Hyperides making mention of them^^^; but 
 whether the Three Hundred continued to exist as a corporate 
 body, after the passing of the new law, cannot be ascertained, 
 although it can be hardly doubted thatnews ymmoriae and new 
 leaders were created. 
 
 Demosthenes boasts of his resistance to bribes in the intro- 
 duction of this law; while Dinarchus reproaches him with the 
 most disgraceful and rapacious conduct in the proceeding: 
 Demosthenes extols the fortunate consequences of his mea- 
 sures; but, as iEschines thinks that he has proved, he deprived 
 
 3»* Msch. c. Ctesiph. p. 614. 
 
 ^83 De Corona, p. 260, 21, cf. Di- 
 narch. c. Demosth. p. 33, where the 
 bribery of the Three Hundred is men- 
 tioned. "Wolf p. cxv. after Corsini 
 was aware that Dinarchus and Demos- 
 thenes allude to the same thing ; the 
 points in which we disagree I leave to 
 the consideration of the reader. 
 
 '"^^■^ Hyperides ap. Harpocrat. in v. 
 (TVfifiopLa, compare Pollux viii. 100. 
 The Three Himdred mentioned by 
 Demosthenes de Corona, p. 285, 17, in 
 a narration belonging to Olymp. 110 2 
 (bc. 339), appear to be the three hun- 
 dred of the symraoriae of the property 
 taxes.
 
 574 
 
 FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 the state of the trierarchs of sixty-five swift-sailing triremes^''^ 
 Which shall posterity believe, when it wishes to form a 
 judgment from the accounts of deceitful orators? It appears 
 to me that the statement of Demosthenes is defended by 
 the fact itself, and the general opinion concerning his whole 
 public Hfe. But instead of entering more largely into this 
 subject, I will only attempt to fix the period at which this law 
 was proposed. 
 
 According to a document still extant it was passed on the 
 16th of Boedromion in the archonship of Polycles^''; but 
 unfortunately no year bears his name. Corsini^" places him 
 in Olymp. 109, 4 (b.c. 341), which is called the year of Nico- 
 machus; but if his arguments are closely examined, their weak- 
 ness is soon perceptible. In Olymp. 109, 4, in the archonship 
 of Neocles or Nicocles, which falls in the year of Nicomachus, 
 it was proposed by Aristophon in the prytaneia of the tribe 
 Hippothontis on the last day of Boedromion, to claim from 
 Phihp the ships which he had taken away^^^: the law of Demos- 
 thenes was however passed on the 16th day of Boedromion 
 during the presidency of the same tribe; consequently, says he, 
 Polycles must have been archon in the same year. This con- 
 clusion is perfectly unwarranted. Nothing more follows, than 
 that in the year in which Polycles was archon, the tribe Hippo- 
 thontis had the third prytaneia, and likewise in Olymp. 109, 4; 
 only however in case both were common years: if the. year in 
 which Polycles was archon was an intercalary year, this agree- 
 ment could not have existed, but the same tribe must have had 
 the second prytaneia in that year; but even supposing it was a 
 common year, why should not the tribe Hippothontis have 
 been allotted the same prytaneia in two successive years? 
 Do we not find that the tribe Aiantis often held the first 
 place, although there was no necessity that it should be so^^^ ? 
 
 ^^^ See Dinarclius and yEschines as 
 above. 
 
 =*«« Demosth. de Corona, p. 261. 
 
 397 F. A. vol. i. p. 352. He con- 
 fuses himself however in his inquiry, 
 and this confusion led Wolf into the 
 
 eiTor of supposing that Corsini meant 
 Olymp. 109, 3, when Sosigenes was 
 archon Eiionymus, p. 1 13 sq. 
 
 3»8 Demosth. de Corona, p. 250. 
 
 ^^9 The tribe Aiantis had indeed so 
 far tlie preference that its chorus
 
 CH. XIV.] FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. 575 
 
 Secondly, Corsini asserts that Demosthenes passed the law 
 before the war with PhiHp, which broke out in Olymp. 110, 1 
 (B.C. 340), consequently it must belong to the year mentioned 
 before. But I am unable to discover any proof that the law 
 was passed before the war. 
 
 Petit'*" on the other hand places the archon Polycles in 
 Olymp. 110, 2 (b.c. 339). For in Olymp. 110, 1, PhiHp 
 attacked Byzantium and Perinthus; and on this occasion the 
 Athenians, according to the account of Philochorus, equipped a 
 fleet upon the instigation of Demosthenes, who was the author 
 of the decrees, and also continued their preparations in the 
 succeeding year. Now Demosthenes, after having related that 
 Byzantium and the Chersonese were saved by his counsel, men- 
 tions the law concerning the trierarchy as the next service 
 which he had rendered the state*"'. The supposition of Petit 
 therefore appears to be well founded. 
 
 But it might be assumed with greater probability that the 
 law was passed in Olymp. 110, 1, in the month Boedromion, 
 that is in the autumn, about the month of September. Phihp, 
 according to the account of Philochorus, made an attack upon 
 Perinthus in the archonship of Theophrastus in Olymp. 110, 1, 
 and, when this undertaking had failed, upon the city of Byzan- 
 tium: it appears however that this either took place at the very 
 beginning of this civil year, or at the end of the former year, 
 ■vHz. in the summer of Olymp. 109, 4, and Olymp. 110, 1, which 
 is signified by the new archon of the civil year which began in 
 the middle of this summer, and not by the archon of the pre- 
 ceding year which ended in the middle of the same summer. 
 For the historians reckon the natural year from spring to 
 spring: if then they wish to express the same year by the name 
 of the archon, or, what is the same thing, to compare it with 
 
 could never be the last (Plutarcli Qu. •'<"' Leg. Att. iii. 4, 8. 
 Symp. i. 10). In the allotment of the j ^"^ Philochor, pp. 75, 76, of the col- 
 prytaneias, it was however on pre- lection of his Fragments published by 
 cisely the same footing as the rest, ! Lenz and Siebelis. Demosth. de Co- 
 and might be the last : of which an in- rona, p. 260, 4, ^ovXofiai roivvv enaveX- 
 stance occurs in Demosth. de Corona, ^eti/, e^' a tovtcov e^rjs enoXiTevofjLTjv. 
 p. 289.
 
 576 FOURTH FORM OF TRIERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 the civil year, the natural method would be to choose the civil 
 year of which three-fourths coincided with the natural one, and 
 not the preceding year, which has only three months in com- 
 mon. If this is true, and the next summer of Olymp. 110, ^ is 
 not meant, the preparations must have been made in the same 
 autumn, in the beginning of Olymp. 110, 1, and Demosthenes 
 carried through the law concerning the trierarchy about the 
 September of Olymp. 110, 1, in order that in the following 
 campaign the war might be carried on in the spring with better 
 success; the archon Polycles must therefore be placed in the 
 year in which Theophrastus was archon Eponymus. There 
 cannot however be any doubt between any other years except 
 Olymp. 110, 1, and 2. 
 
 Of the duration of this law we know nothing, as we have no 
 accounts concerning later times. In the oration for the Crown 
 (Olymp. 112,3, B.C. 330), in which so much is said upon this 
 subject, it is neither mentioned that this law was still in 
 existence, nor that it had been repealed, nor that anything 
 had been substituted in its place; it appears, however, that 
 ^schines, influenced by the bribes of the leaders of the 
 symmoriee, succeeded in procuring its abrogation*"*. 
 
 Chapter XV. 
 
 General Observations upon the Expense of a Trierarchy. 
 
 From what has been said it is evident that the trierarchy, the 
 most expensive of the liturgies, was not necessarily oppressive, 
 if the regulations connected with it were fairly and properly 
 arranged, though on the other hand no tax was more intolerable, 
 if the burthens were unequally imposed and distributed: for 
 thus it frequently happened that the property of those who 
 from motives of ambition or patriotism were induced to incur 
 greater expenses than were necessary, was exhausted by it. 
 Accordingly, not only were the rich impoverished by the 
 liturgies*"^ but they corrupted the people by their lavish 
 
 Domosth. de Corona, p. :\2\K "'•^ Xenoph. Rep. Atli. i. 13.
 
 CH. XV.] EXPENSE OF A TRIERARCHY. 577 
 
 expenditure, as the sailors are said to have been by Apollo- 
 dorus, the son of Pasion, when trierarch^°^; we must not there- 
 fore be surprised at the exaggerations of the comic poet* % who, 
 in order to show the insecurity of all property which a man did 
 not hold, as it were, between his teeth, says that the payer of 
 property taxes might be utterly ruined by them, the choregus 
 could furnish his chorus with golden dresses, and leave himself 
 afterwards in rags; and the trierarch hang himself in despair. 
 
 But similar measures have also been employed in our days, 
 though under other circumstances, and in a somewhat different 
 form. If the ancients had been as well acquainted with the 
 pressure of armies living at free quarter, of war supplies and 
 forced loans, as we in the present time are with their liturgies, 
 they would have had more to apprehend from the introduction of 
 our system than we could have of theirs; especially as the means 
 of legal redress were then far more accessible than in modern 
 times. If we (in Germany) had the same publicity of govern- 
 ment and freedom of discussion as existed in Greece, as many 
 stories to our prejudice would descend to our posterity as have 
 been handed down to us in the works of their orators on the 
 subject of the liturgies; and if the persons who were liable to 
 war taxes, or who had soldiers quartered on them, were allowed 
 to challenge an exchange of property with any one who might 
 appear better able to bear these burdens, the same number of 
 courts of justice as existed at Athens would hardly suffice 
 to decide the disputes which would arise in a city of equal 
 extent*. 
 
 With regard to the trierarchy, although the expenses 
 required were very different at different times, the statements 
 of the ancients all lead to the same result, viz. that a whole 
 trierarchy did not cost less than 40 minas, nor more than a 
 talent; and that a half trierarchy cost between 20 and 30 
 minas, except in such a case as that of ApoUodorus, where 
 
 *"■* Demosth. c. Polyclem. 
 •*"* Antiphanes ap. Athen. iii. p. 
 103 F. 
 
 * [It is to be borne in mind that 
 
 the original of this work was pub- 
 lished in 1817, a time when the re- 
 flections in the text might naturally 
 occur to a German. — Transl.] 
 2 P
 
 578 EXPENSE OF A TRTERARCHY. [bK. IV. 
 
 the trierarch supplied the pay, or subjected himself to other 
 unnecessary expenses, or managed his affairs without economy. 
 
 A trierarchy which lasted for three years after the battle of 
 Cnidus, cost, according to Lysias, 80 minas*"% that is, upon an 
 average, 26f a year, which was doubtless only a half or syn- 
 trierarchy; in the later times of the Peloponnesian war a 
 trierarchy of two partners cost 48 minas, 24 a-piece**'^ The 
 half trierarchy which was let by Demosthenes, cost 20 minas, 
 the state neither providing the equipment, nor even supplying 
 the crew. 
 
 At a subsequent period the lease of a whole trierarchy cost 
 a talent, although the vessels were both manned and equipped 
 by the state'"', which may be explained by supposing that the 
 contractors, who had before reckoned upon captures, and there- 
 fore required less assistance, had been taught by former losses 
 to raise their demands; the ship^s furniture might also have 
 been damaged and imperfect, and the vessels themselves in 
 want of much repair. A whole trierarchy for seven years in 
 earlier times (from Olymp. 92, 2, until Olymp. 93, 4, B.C. 411 
 — 5), had cost a client of Lysias 6 talents, that is, 51^ minas a 
 year*•'^ 
 
 But the proportion which the services bore to the property, 
 before a correct allotment had been enforced by law, cannot be 
 ascertained, on account of the absence of a fair scale founded 
 upon fixed principles. The only question therefore of which 
 we can offer any solution is, what was the amount of property 
 which obliged the citizens to the performance of the trierarchy; 
 even upon this point however we are unable to state a determi- 
 nate sum, although some fixed rate must have existed. 
 
 ApoUodorus the trierarch had an annual income of 2 
 talents*'"; the family of Demosthenes, which was liable to the 
 performance of the trierarchy, an estate of 15 talents*' ', that 
 produced at the least an income of 90 minas a year, and 
 
 *o« Pro Aristoph. bonis, p. G33, p. 
 643. 
 
 4"7 Lysias c. Diogit. pp. 907—909. 
 
 *°8 See chap. 12 and 13. 
 
 "'^ Book iii. cli. 22. 
 ^•° Book iv. ch. 3. 
 ^" Book iv. ch. 3
 
 CH. XV.J EXPENSE OF A TRIERARCHY. 579 
 
 Isaeus''^ complains that a person with an income of 80 minas, 
 which supposes a property of about 1 1 talents, had not per- 
 formed any trierarchy. Critobulus, as mentioned in Xeno- 
 phon*^% had a property of more than 500 minas, which would 
 subject him, in the opinion of Socrates, among other expenses 
 to the pay of more than one trierarchy, in case a war should 
 break out; that is to say, he would be forced to perform the 
 syntrierarchy, which had been introduced about twelve years 
 before the death of Socrates, and which was in existence when 
 Xenophon wTote this passage. The word 7j«?/ is used because 
 a trierarch who did not command his own vessel, made a pay- 
 ment to the other trierarch who served in person, which appears 
 to be in strictness a remuneration for services performed. I 
 am aware of no instance of liability to the trierarchy arising 
 from a property of less amount than this; and since an estate of 
 1 or 2 talents never obliged the possessor to the performance of 
 any liturg}^*^*, what shall be said to the assertion of Is8eus*'*, that 
 many had borne the expensive office of trierarch, whose property 
 did not amount to 80 minas ? If this is not a rhetorical exag- 
 geration, or a deceit on the part of the rich, who, by concealing 
 their property, wished to enjoy the credit of a greater sacrifice, 
 while they only performed their just share, these must have been 
 services performed by ambitious and public-spirited citizens, 
 who did not hesitate to contribute to a syntrierarchy a con- 
 siderable portion of a small property. The same judgment may 
 be formed on the case of another client of the same orator*' ^ 
 who defrayed the expenses of a gymnasiarchy from a supposed 
 fortune of about 83 minas. 
 
 •*^- De Dicaeog. Hered. p. 110. j was never bound to furnish the pay, 
 
 •*^3 (Econ. 2, 6, Tptrjpapxias pnaOovs. | and if pay were meant, the expression 
 
 Pay for the sailors cannot be here used must have been pna-Qovs vavrav 
 
 meant. Reckoning the pay without and not rpirjpapxLas. 
 
 the pro\ision at 20 minas a month, al- I *'"* See book iii. ch. 21. 
 
 though 30 were often given, the result *^' De Dicaeog. Hered. ubi sup 
 
 would be such a sum as no trierarch ""^^ De Menecl. Hered. pp. 219—223. 
 
 overpaid or could pay; we have also Orell. 
 
 sufficiently proved that the trierarch 
 
 P 2
 
 580 
 
 THE ANTIDOSIS. 
 
 [bk. 
 
 Chapter XVI. 
 
 The Antidosis, or compulsory Exchange of Property, 
 
 At the conclusion of our researches concerning the liturgies, 
 it will be necessary to say something on the subject of the 
 exchange (avr/Soo-t?). 
 
 For the purpose of relieving the poor^ and particularly those 
 whose property had been diminished by reverses of fortune^ '% 
 from the oppression of an unfair burden^ and in order to pre- 
 vent the wealthy from escaping the liturgies, it was enacted by 
 law that whoever named another person to a liturgy, whom he 
 thought to have been passed over, though better able to under- 
 take it than himself, was empowered to transfer it; and in case 
 the latter party refused to take it, he could demand an exchange 
 of property, with the condition that he should then perform the 
 liturgy from the property received by him in exchange; and 
 the party, to whom the exchange had been oiFered, could no 
 longer be called upon to perform if^^ Solon was the author 
 of this regulation, which, though obviously subject to many 
 difficulties, was neither unjust nor absurd^^% and it provided a 
 ready means of redress against arbitrary oppression. To assist 
 every man in obtaining his right, and to afford protection to the 
 poor, were the predominant objects of the legislation of Solon, 
 which he pursued without paying any regard to the inconve- 
 niences which might arise from the means employed in attaining 
 them. 
 
 The exchange most frequently occurred in the case of the 
 trierarchy, and not uncommonly in that of the choregia"-"; it 
 existed, however, in the other liturgies, and could also be had 
 recourse to as a relief from the property taxes, if, for example, 
 any one complained that his means were not greater than those 
 
 *-7 Orat. c. Phaenipp. pp. 1039, 1040. 
 ''^^ Suidas in v. avridoais, Lex. Seg. 
 p. 197, Ulpian ad Mid. p. 660 A. 
 *'^ Orat. c. Phsenipp. init. 
 
 ^'" Xenoph. fEcon. 7, 3, Lysias 7rep\ 
 Tov dSvvar. p. 745, Demosth. c. Lept. 
 § 109 (p. 496, 20), c. Mid. n. 565, 8.
 
 CH. XVI.] 
 
 THE ANTIDOSIS. 
 
 581 
 
 of some other person who was rated to a lower class, or, as 
 was frequently the case, that persons could prove themselves 
 unfairly included in the class of the Three Hundred"'. This 
 proceeding was allowed every year to the persons nominated 
 for the liturgies by the regular authorities, which in the case of 
 the trierarchy and property taxes were the generals"*, to the 
 great delay of military aifairs. The offerer immediately laid a 
 sequestration upon the property of his opponent, and sealed up 
 his house, if he refused to accept the liturgy; the house was 
 however free to the first party. The next step was that both 
 the parties undertook upon oath to give an account of their pro- 
 perty, and were bound within the space of three days to deliver 
 in an inventory [airo^avcns) to each other. Then the cause 
 was decided by the court^^^. If the decision was unfavourable 
 to the party who made the offer, the proposed exchange did not 
 take place; and it was in this manner that Isocrates gained his 
 cause by means of his son Aphareus, against Megacleides, who 
 had demanded to exchange property with him. If however the 
 decision was in favour of the oflferer, the opponent was free 
 either to accept the exchange, or to perform the liturgy. On 
 that account Isocrates undertook the third of the three trie- 
 rarchies performed by himself and his son, when Lysimachus 
 liad claimed to exchange with him''^*; and it is to this the 
 oration concerning the exchange refers, a speech of great 
 length, but barren of information. Lastly, the party to whom 
 the ofi"er was made, could not bring the cause into court, 
 after the seal had been once imposed; but he was then 
 
 ''2' Orat. c. Phaenipp. particularly p. 
 1046, 24, from whence it is pretty cer- 
 tain that the question in the speech 
 relates to the advance of the taxes. 
 Concerning translation from one class 
 into another, compare also the argu- 
 ment to this oration. 
 
 4^^ Orat. c. Phtenipp. p. 1040, De- 
 mosth. Philipp. i. p. 50, 20, Xenoph. 
 Rep. Ath. 3, 4 ; comp. Suidas in the 
 passage quoted by MattliiaB, Miscell. 
 Philolog, vol. i. p. 249. 
 
 *'^'^ Orat. c. Pha3uipp. cf. Xenopli. 
 
 ubi sup. (unless it be thought that law 
 suits wdth regard to ship's furniture 
 are here meant, see the speech against 
 Euergus and Mnesib. p. 1148, I? sqq.) 
 Suid. in v. diadiKaa-ia. 
 
 ^2-» Isocrat. de Antid. 2, ed. Hall, p. 
 80, ed. Orell. Comp. the inaccm-ate 
 account in the Lives of the Ten Orators, 
 p. 240, and the more correct one in 
 p. 244. Dionys. Halicarn. Vit. Di- 
 narch. ad fin. Aphareus is also men- 
 tioned as triei-arch in Orat. c. Euerg. 
 et Mnesib. p. 1148.
 
 582 THE AXTIDOSIS. [bK. IV. 
 
 obliged to take the liturgy; as was the case with Demos- 
 thenes^". 
 
 All immoveable and moveable property was transferred in 
 the exchange, with the exception only of mines''^% which were 
 exempted from the extraordinary taxes and the liturgies, as 
 being already taxed. On the other hand, Wesseling upon 
 Petit maintains that all actions, and Wolf that all civil actions, 
 of the parties making the exchange, were transferred from the 
 one to the other. Both regulations are too absurd to be 
 imputed to the Athenian law. With regard to public actions it 
 is evident at first sight that this could not have been the prac- 
 tice. We will suppose that Demosthenes and Thrasylochus 
 exchanged their property, and that Demosthenes had an action 
 for illegal proceedings pending against him; if then Demos- 
 thenes was afterwards condemned to death, is Thrasylochus 
 to be executed? No one indeed imagined this possible; but 
 supposing Demosthenes was condemned to a fine of 50 talents, 
 is Thrasylochus to pay the fine, and in case of failure to be 
 thrown into prison, and to suffer whatever were the other con- 
 sequences of such omission ? A regulation of this kind would 
 be impossible, for the law could only punish the person who 
 actually committed the offence. The case is precisely the same 
 with civil or private cases. If Thrasylochus struck Callias, or 
 injured his property in any manner, and an action was brought 
 against him before the exchange took place, and after it had 
 been completed, was condemned to pay to Calhas a certain 
 sum for damages, Demosthenes is evidently not bound to pay 
 this sum; for the liabiUty is personal, and necessarily continues 
 so. Or if Thrasylochus had a private law suit relating to some 
 mining affair, the mines being a species of property which was 
 excluded from the exchange, it is manifest that when the 
 exchange was made, the law suit could not have been trans- 
 ferred to Demosthenes. 
 
 Now let us suppose another case. Demosthenes brings an 
 action against Aphobus for having damaged his property, and 
 
 *** C. Aphob.ii. p. «41, c.Mid. p. 540. I my Dissertation upou the Silver Mines 
 *''^^ Orat. c. Phaeuipp. p. 1044. Com. | of Laurium.
 
 CH. XVI.] THE ANTIDOSIS. 583 
 
 demands a compensation of 10 talents: while the case is 
 pending^ he exchanges his property with Thrasylochus; in this 
 instance it is agreeable to common sense that the cause should 
 pass over to Thrasylochus, who is at liberty either to proceed 
 with itj or allow it to fall to the ground; and if he adopts the 
 former course, he has no one to blame for the issue of it but 
 himself. In otlier words, the parties making the exchange 
 transferred their property, mines being excepted, with all claims 
 and obligations attached to it, and particularly all debts, as 
 may be seen from the speech against Pheenippus. This holds 
 good of every other transfer of property, even when there was 
 no interchange: whoever received an estate by inheritance, 
 received also the rights and duties belonging to it: and with 
 regard to the exchange the same rule obtained. 
 
 The single case from which it has been inferred that law 
 suits were transferred in the exchange, exactly proves what has 
 been stated. When the action of Demosthenes against his 
 guardians (from whom he claimed compensation for the pro- 
 perty of which they had defrauded him, and thus in fact 
 demanded restitution of what had formerly belonged to him, 
 as of an unpaid debt) was to have come before the court in a 
 few days, Thrasylochus offered to exchange property with him, 
 having a secret understanding with the guardians, that if Demos- 
 thenes accepted the offer, he (Thrasylochus) would not proceed 
 with the cause against them; because these law suits, as 
 the orator expressly says, were transferred to the party who 
 made the exchange**^ Demosthenes accepted the exchange, 
 reserving, however, his claims upon the guardians, in the 
 hope of a judicial decision, by which the reservation would 
 be granted to him: failing, however, to attain this object, 
 and as there was no time to be lost, he cancelled his agree- 
 ment to the exchange, and performed the trierarchy, in order 
 that he might not give up the cause against his guardians, to 
 whom his opponent had already yielded the dispute''^\ 
 
 ''^^ C. Aphob. ii. p. 840 ext. tv' el j dvTibovros yiyvofxevcou. 
 fxev dvTi8(OT]v, fxr) c^eir] fxoi npos avTovs \ ^'■^ Ibid. p. 841, c. Mid. p. 539 sqq. 
 avTidmelv, cos Koi tu>v 8ik(ov tovtoov tov \
 
 584 MEANS EMPLOYED TO [bK. 
 
 Chapter XVII. . 
 
 Extraordinary means employed by the Greek States to relieve 
 pecuniary difficulties: namely y Foreign Subsidies, Plunder, 
 Captures, forced and voluntary Contributions, 
 
 Notwithstanding the extensive resources of Athens and her 
 various means of raising money, she shared the common fate of 
 the Grecian states, and was frequently exposed to the greatest 
 difficulty by an inability to pay comparatively trifling sums, 
 arising from the want both of foresight and economy in the 
 management of the revenue''"^ Thus Athens, after the 
 anarchy, at a time when the state was completely exhausted, 
 was driven into hostilities w4th the Boeotians, by an inability to 
 raise 2 talents""; and subsequently the Thebans themselves 
 were prevented from recovering their citadel from the foreigners 
 by being in like manner unable to raise 5 talents; and an expe- 
 dition of all the Arcadians failed in attaining its object from a 
 want of 9 talents'"^ It is not therefore surprising that the 
 states of Greece resorted to other means of raising money than 
 those that have been already mentioned, and particularly for 
 defraying the expenses of war. 
 
 Among these may be mentioned the Persian subsidies, 
 which were chiefly obtained by Sparta for the purpose of being 
 employed against Athens*^^. The occasions upon which the 
 latter state receiv^ed support from the king of Persia or his 
 satraps were rare, as for example, through Alcibiades and 
 Conon; in the contests against Macedon, when it was the policy 
 of the Persian king to assist the Athenians with money, he at 
 first refused it in a coarse and barbarous epistle; and shortly 
 afterwards, when it was too late, and the Athenians no longer 
 ventured to accept any aid, he off'ered them 300 talents. 
 
 ^*^ Instances of embarrassment see 
 iu Thucyd. viii. 4, and above book iii. 
 ch. 19. 
 
 *'" Lys. c. Nicomach. p. 860. 
 
 "' ^sch. c. Ctesiph. p. 633. 
 
 ^32 More than 5000 talents; see 
 book i. ch. 3. This took place later 
 than Olynip. 91, 4 (b.c. 413), as is 
 shown by Andoc. de Pace, p. 103, cf. 
 Thucyd. viii. 5.
 
 en. 
 
 XVII.] RELIEVE I^ECUXIARY DIFFICULTIES. 
 
 585 
 
 Another productive source of revenue*^^ was the plunder 
 obtained in war; for according to the international law of the 
 ancientSj the bodies of all prisoners, together with their wives, 
 children^ and slaves, and their whole property, moveable and 
 immoveable, became the property of the conqueror ; and it 
 was only by particular stipulations that milder conditions were 
 obtained; for example, that the free population of a conquered 
 city should be permitted to go out with a single garment each, 
 or to pay a large contribution, or to cultivate their own lands 
 upon the payment of a rent. The troops were also frequently 
 paid out of the plunder; and the conquered land was theu 
 immediately sold. The Athenian generals also in one instance 
 received 60 talents for nine triremes, w^hich had been captured 
 from Dionysius''^*. For reprisals against the enemy they were 
 in the habit of taking prisoners {dvBpoXyyfrLa, avhpoXrj^iovY^^, 
 and granted, both against states and individuals, permission to 
 privateer (aOXa, avXaL)*^^. A prize-court decided upon the 
 plunder which was taken*^^; the tenth part of which was allotted 
 to the temple of Minerva^^^, and the rest must have belonged 
 to the adventurers: under certain circumstances however it fell 
 to the state*^% and the proceeds were frequently considerable. 
 Thus a ship of Naucratis, which the court had adjudged to the 
 state, was estimated at 9^ talents''*''. 
 
 The contributions, which were imposed upon conquered 
 states, were sometimes of large amount; Pericles raised 80 and 
 at another time 200 talents from the island of Samos as a fine 
 and compensation for the expenses of the war, for which indeed 
 they were not sufficient'"'; at times they were taken not from 
 the whole state, but from individuals whose principles were not 
 
 *33 ^schin. ubi sup. p. 632 sq. cf. 
 Dinarch. c. Uemosth, p. 14, where the 
 same occurrence is probably alluded to. 
 
 *3* Diod. XV. 47, xvi. 57. 
 
 *35 See Petit Leg. Att. vii, 1. 17, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 213. 
 
 ^^® Conceruiug the avXas diBovai, 
 comp. e. g. Demosth. c. Lacrit. p. 931, 
 23. 
 
 ^37 Cf. Salraas. M. U. p. 211 sqq. 
 Liban. Argum. ad Demosth, c. Timo- 
 crat. p. 694, 20. 
 
 *^^ See book iii. ch. 6. 
 
 ^39 Demosth. c. Timocrat. and Liba- 
 nius ubi sup. 
 
 ^■^^ Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 696, 5, 
 14, p. 703, 15. 
 
 **' Diod. xii. 27, 28, Thucyd. i. 117.
 
 586 
 
 MEANS EMPLOYED TO 
 
 [bk. IV. 
 
 agreeable to the ruling power''^^ In general^ ho^yever, these 
 contributions had the character of mere arbitrary extortions 
 alike from friends and foes; vessels were dispatched in order to 
 collect money {apyvpoXoyelv, BaajjLo\oyelv)**^, and not legal tri- 
 butes alone but additional contributions, which impoverished 
 the ill-fated inhabitants of the islands; Alcibiades, who had a 
 particular dexterity in business of this description, and to 
 whom they were most willing to give contributions, raised 100 
 talents in Caria alone^". The Athenians went about as pirates, 
 in order to defray the expenses of war; and this even in the 
 earlier and better times of Athens, for we find that Miltiades 
 undertook an expedition for plunder against Paros, in order to 
 raise 100 talents*^^ They also imposed fines upon different 
 states for particular offences; thus for example the Melians, (or 
 according to another reading, the Tenians,) were required to 
 pay a fine of 10 talents, for having harboured pirates in their 
 island, which sum was collected with violence^". 
 
 Lastly, a source of revenue by no means unproductive 
 existed in the calls frequently made in the assembly*^' for 
 voluntary contributions {eTTtSocrecs), either in money, arms, or 
 ships; and these, as they smoothed the way to popular favour, 
 and as many were either willing to sacrifice all they had to the 
 good of their country, or expected advantage to themselves 
 from its prosperity, were bestowed largely by citizens and 
 foreigners, especially such as were endeavouring to obtain the 
 rights of citizenship. The voluntary trierarchies and the great 
 sacrifices which were made in the earlier times for the expe- 
 dition to Sicily, have been already mentioned; Pasion the 
 banker furnished 1000 shields from his own manufactory, 
 together with five triremes which he manned at his own cost*"*^; 
 Chrysippus presented a talent to the state, when Alexander 
 moved against Thebes, and afterwards the same sum for the 
 
 **^ An instance occurs in Diod. xiii. 
 47. 
 
 **^ Tliucyd. iii. IJJ, and frequently in 
 the Historians. 
 
 ''' Xenoph. HeUen. i. 4, 4. 
 
 *^^ Herod, vi. 130. 
 
 *'^ Orat. c. 
 —28. 
 
 Theocrin. p. 1339, 2 
 
 ^•'^ Demosth. c. Mid. p. 567, Plu- 
 tarch. Alcib. 10, Theophrast. Char. 22, 
 Athen. iv. p. 168, E. Plutarch. Phoc. 9. 
 
 *^» Demosth. c. Steph. p. 1127, 12.
 
 CH. XVII.] RELIEVE PECUNIARY DIFFICULTIES. 
 
 5S7 
 
 purpose of purchasing corn'''; Aristophanes, the son of Nico- 
 pheraus, gave 30,000 drachmas for an expedition against 
 Cyprus""; Nausicles, general of the hoplit® in Imbros, sup- 
 plied 2000 men with pay without requiring any compensation 
 from the state; Charidemus and Diotimus, two other comman- 
 ders, made a free gift of 800 shields'*''; Demosthenes not only 
 performed voluntary liturgies and contributed money for the 
 public works, but gave on diflferent occasions three triremes, 
 and also at one time eight talents, to which he afterwards added 
 three more for the building of the walls, one talent after the 
 battle of Cheeronea, and another for the purchase of corn*". 
 As they were accustomed to give presents upon so large a scale, 
 Isseus"^ might well reproach Dicaeogenes, who was possessed of 
 an income of 80 minas, with having given no more than 300 
 drachmas, even less than Cleonymus the Cretan. It is singular 
 that voluntary contributions were not claimed for wars only, or 
 to assist the people during a scarcity of provisions, but even for 
 sacrifices'*'*. 
 
 Chapter XVIII. 
 Public Loans. 
 
 Of the other measures by which the Greeks endeavoured to 
 provide for any temporary difficulty of the state, and of which 
 the second book of the CEconomics attributed to Aristotle fur- 
 nishes a considerable collection, I will now mention some of 
 the most remarkable, although many are not better than 
 common tricks of roguery and swindling. 
 
 Of these the most frequent, and indeed the least objection- 
 able, is the borrowing of money, which was not so extensively 
 practised in ancient as in modern times, both because credit 
 was at a low ebb, and also because the high rate of interest was 
 a great obstacle to the creation of a national debt; besides 
 which their system of finance had not the solidity nor was of 
 
 *^» Demosth. c. Pliorm. p. 918, inf. 
 '*" Lys. pro Aristoph. bonis p. 644. 
 ^*' Demosth. de Corona, p. 265. 
 
 4^ Decret. ap. Vit. x. Orat. p. 275 sq. 
 453 De DicsBOg. llered. j). 111. 
 4*-' Plutarch. Thoc. 'J.
 
 588 PUBLIC LOANS. [bK. IV. 
 
 the artificial nature which this method of raising money 
 requires; hence they preferred procuring the necessary supphes 
 immediately by a property tax_, to borrowing the necessary sum 
 and aften\'ards repaying it at a high interest. We do however 
 find examples of loans of various kinds (either from foreign 
 states and individuals, or from the inhabitants of the state 
 itself), as of property sacred or not sacred, paying or not pay- 
 ing a rent, with or without security, voluntary or compulsory, 
 and sometimes with a certain allowance of a currency of tokens. 
 The loans of most frequent occurrence were those obtained 
 by a state from its own citizens, as they required the least credit 
 and were most easily eflfected: rich aliens at x\thens under the 
 protection of the state sometimes made a voluntary oflfer of 
 lending money*": a loan to one state from a citizen of another 
 occurs in an Orchomenian Inscription*. Sparta furnished the 
 Samians, w-ho endeavoured to reconquer their native country, 
 with a sum of money which they raised by a public decree in 
 a manner w^hich seems more amusing to us than it could have 
 been agreeable to the Spartans. It was eflfected by the inha- 
 bitants fasting for one day together with their slaves and cattle^ 
 and each person was obliged to contribute to the state the same 
 quantity that he would have consumed''^^ for which probably 
 no repayment was required. This state also lent 100 talents to 
 the Tliirty Tyrants at Athens; w^hich the people, whether from 
 love of justice, as Demosthenes affirms, or through fear of the 
 Spartans, redeemed by a general property tax, though some 
 persons required, and not without an appearance of justice, that 
 those who had incurred the debt should pay if*". In this loan 
 there was doubtless neither interest nor security. Loans of 
 money belonging to the temples frequently occur, and, for the 
 
 ■»** It was however necessary for ' the same story of a present of corn 
 them to avoid committing any solecism sent by the Spartans to the Sniyr- 
 in their language which could shock j nseans. Are we to suppose that this 
 
 the Athenian ear, if they wished their 
 proposal to be accepted. Photius in 
 V. Bepici). 
 
 * Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 1569. 
 
 *^'^ Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 9, Plutarch, 
 (de Discrim. Amic. et Adul. 33), relates 
 
 generous action was repeated, or that 
 one of the accounts is untrue ? 
 
 ••^7 Demosth. c. Leptin. § 10, 11, 
 Isocrat. Areop. 28, Lysias c. Nicoiii. 
 p. 800, Xenoph. Hell. ii. 4, 19, Plu- 
 tarch. Lysand. 21.
 
 CH. XVIII.] 
 
 PUBLIC LOANS. 
 
 589 
 
 most part without interest**®. Besides the large sums of money 
 which Athens borrowed from its temples, it may be also men- 
 tioned, that the temple of Delos, which was under the power of 
 Athens, had lent money upon interest to private individuals, 
 and even to many states*". The money deposited in the hands 
 of Lycurgus, and advanced by him for the use of the adminis- 
 tration, may be considered as a loan of private individuals 
 without interest. 
 
 Of a security or pledge in the case of public loans there are 
 but few examples : Memnon of Rhodes, the governor of Lamp- 
 sacus, assigned to the creditors the national revenues which 
 were next due ; Tachus, the king of Egypt, did the same, upon 
 the advice of Chabrias*^"; the Oreitge of Eubcea are stated to 
 have pledged the public revenues to Demosthenes for a debt 
 bearing interest ^®^; and at Orchomenus the cattle-pastures 
 appear to have been given to an Elatean, as a security for a 
 loan of money*^^ 
 
 Compulsory loans are all those which were imposed upon 
 certain persons by a decree of the people, or the command of 
 a tyrant, either because they were particularly rich or in the 
 possession of those objects which were required. The advance 
 of taxes made by the wealthy Athenians^" belongs generically 
 to this class, although there is a difference in the form, for the 
 state was not, in this instance, the debtor, but the poorer 
 citizens, who escaped the equal proportion of the taxes. The 
 Chians obtained a forced loan, which fell solely upon the 
 capitalists, in the following manner: they ordered that all the 
 money lent out to private individuals, which in this island was 
 entered in a public register, should be delivered up by the 
 debtors to the state, which then undertook their obligations, 
 and engaged itself to pay the interest out of the public 
 revenue until it was able to redeem the principal"^ Diony- 
 sius the elder, and Tachus, required all the uncoined gold 
 and silver to be lent to the state : the Mendaeans, wishing to 
 
 *-^^ Corp. Inscript. Nos. 76 and 144. 
 "^^ Corp. Inscript. No. 158. 
 '^<* Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 20, 25. Cf. 
 Polygen. v. 11, 5. 
 
 ■*«' .ICschin. c. Ctesiph. p. 496. 
 
 ^^^ Corp. Inscript. No. 1569. 
 
 ^^ See book iv. ch, 9. 
 
 '^^ Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 12.
 
 590 PUBLIC LOANS. [bK. IV. 
 
 raise money for the war against Olynthus, decreed that every 
 person should sell all his slaves, with the exception of one 
 female and one male, in order to lend to the state the money 
 which accrued from the sale : the Clazomenians passed a decree 
 compelling private individuals to advance all their stock of oil, 
 a commodity which was produced in that state in great 
 abundance, in consideration of the payment of a sum of money, 
 with a view to remedy the scarcity of corn : the Ephesians 
 prohibited the women from wearing gold ornaments, and com- 
 pelled them to deliver what they had as a loan to the state"". 
 The Clazomenians owed 20 talents to their mercenaries for 
 arrears of pay, for which they paid a yearly interest of 4 talents 
 to the commanders ; thus they were continually making useless 
 payments, without arriving any nearer to the redemption of 
 the debt. They, therefore, coined 20 talents of iron money, to 
 which they arbitrarily gave the value of silver, distributed it 
 proportionally among the most wealthy, and received an equal 
 quantity of silver in return, by which they redeemed the debt"^\ 
 The iron, which was thrown into circulation by the possessors, 
 replaced the silver as a currency of tokens, and therefore the 
 quantity of money in circulation was not diminished ; the iron 
 money performed the same service at home as the silver 
 formerly, and whatever silver they possessed besides that 
 furnished to the state, could be used for foreign exchanges. So 
 far then this iron coinage stood to them in the same relation as 
 the paper money of modern days. But the state also paid an 
 interest to those persons whose silver it had received, and 
 gradually redeemed the iron for silver: thus these iron coins 
 also served the purpose of a certificate of debt. It is manifest 
 that the interest must have been small ; for they probably gave 
 less than the common rate, as the creditors also possessed the 
 current tokens : if the state paid 10 per cent., with the 4 talents 
 which were formerly given to the commanders every year, it 
 might have both paid the interest and redeemed the principal 
 in about eight years. 
 
 •*" Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 20, 25 (cf. | •"^'' Aristot. (Econ. ii. IG. 
 Polysen. V. 11,5), 21, 16, 19.
 
 CH. XIX.] ALTERATIONS IN THE CURRENCY. 
 
 591 
 
 It hardly deserves to be mentioned that states as well as 
 private individuals gave bonds of debt, which were sometimes 
 deposited in the hands of private individuals"^^, particularly of 
 bankers, and sometimes, if the money had been borrowed from 
 sacred corporations, in temples, &c''^''. 
 
 Chapter XIX. 
 
 Alterations in the Currency, as a Financial Ea?pedient. 
 
 A fraudulent method of assisting the finances, which was 
 only effectual for the moment, and in the sequel produced the 
 most pernicious consequences, was the coining of base kinds of 
 money. 
 
 Many Grecian states, even in the time of Solon, openly 
 made use of silver money alloyed with lead or copper'*"^, which, 
 although it was not productive of any disadvantage to the 
 inland traffic of the country, was either wholly or nearly devoid 
 of value in foreign exchanges. It happened, however, but 
 seldom that the state was an intentional coiner of false money; 
 a charge which nevertheless falls with justice upon Dionysius 
 the Elder, who left no evil means untried of putting his tyran- 
 nical projects into execution. In order to pay a sum of money 
 which he had borrowed from the citizens for defraying the 
 expenses of ship-building, he compelled the creditors to receive 
 a coinage of tin, which, according to Pollux, who probably 
 follows Aristotle in the constitution of the Syracusans, passed 
 for 4 drachmas, and was only worth 1"^". The same person, on 
 another occasion, being unable to repay a loan which was 
 claimed of him, commanded his subjects upon pain of death to 
 produce all their silver, which he coined and reissued at twice 
 its former value, and then paid the debt at this standard*^ \ 
 
 *«7 Corp. Inscript. No. 1569. 
 
 ^''^ Ibid, No. 76. 
 
 "69 Demosth. c. Timocrat. p. 766, 10. 
 Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 3. 
 
 ''^o Aristot. CEcon. ii. 2, 20 ; Pollux, 
 viii. 79. That Dionysius the Elder is 
 
 here meant, is shown by the siege of 
 the Regini, the date of which is 
 Olymp. 98, 2 (b.c. 387). Cf. Diod. 
 xiv. 111. 
 
 "'^^ This is the meaning of the passage 
 in the CEconomics. The two accounts
 
 592 ALTERATIONS IN THE CURRENCY, [bK. IV. 
 
 An action of similar dishonesty had been before committed at 
 Athens, by Hippias the Pisistratid. He called in all the silver 
 in circulation, which was taken at a fixed value ; and after- 
 wards, a new device having been agreed upon, he reissued the 
 silver at a higher value than that at which it had been paid 
 in*'*. Republican Athens, on the other hand, anxiously main- 
 tained the purity of her silver coin ; and although the fineness 
 of the standard was latterly somewhat diminished, the state, 
 which had made the forging of coins a capital offence'''^, never 
 chose to derive any profit from the debasement of her silver 
 coinage. 
 
 It is, however, true that Athens, in the archonship of 
 Antigenes (Olymp. 93, 2, B.C. 407), there being at that time a 
 great difificulty in raising money for the extensive military 
 preparations in progress, was reduced to the necessity of 
 coining gold with strong alloy from the statues of Victory*^* ; 
 and in the year which succeeded the issuing of this adulterated 
 money, in the archonship of Callias (Olymp. 93, 3, B.C. 406), 
 a coinage of copper was struck^^% which was soon afterwards 
 recalled^ -^ This copper was doubtless intended to supersede 
 the silver oboli, and must have been issued below its real value, 
 as otherwise there could have been no reason for recalling it 
 from circulation : Athens, however, had some copper coins 
 which were always current, viz., the chalcus, having the value 
 of an eighth obolus, and also the lepta, it being impossible to 
 
 are totally different, although they 
 have been confounded by the same 
 writer. Salmasius (M. U. p. 247) con- 
 
 eys Schol. Aristoph. Ran. 737- 
 ■*76 Aristoph. Eccles. 8J0 sqq. The 
 Commentators upon Aristophanes and 
 
 founds them with one another, and I Eckhel (see book i. ch. 6, note 78) 
 arbitrarily mutilates the words of I have confounded the gold coins alloyed 
 Pollux. with copper and the copper coins ; 
 
 ^"■^ This is the manner in which and if the words of Aristophanes are 
 Aristot. CEcon. ii. 2, 4, should be un- ' correctly explained, it will be seen 
 
 derstood. 
 
 "73 Demosth. c. Lept. p. 508, 13, c. 
 Timocrat. p. 765 extr. 
 
 ^7^ See book i. c. 6. It is to this that 
 
 that the poet speaks of the former in 
 the Frogs, and of the latter in the 
 Ecclesiazus9B : the distinction is also 
 shown by the difference in the yeai'S, 
 
 Demetrius alludes, Trept ipfirfv. § 281, { which the Scholiast states upon good 
 and thence Quintilian I. O. ix. 2. 92, j authority. 
 " Victoiiis utondum esse." 1
 
 CH. XIX.] AS A FINANCIAL EXPEDIENT. 593 
 
 coin silver in such minute pieces. These copper coins were 
 perhaps introduced by the statesman and elegiac poet Diony- 
 sius surnamed the Brazen, who in Olymp. 84, 1 (b.c. 444), 
 went as leader of the colony to Thurii*", and consequently can 
 hardly be considered as the originator of these monetary 
 regulations, which were made in the 93rd Olympiad. Lastly, 
 passing over the copper-money of Athens, in the times of the 
 emperors, I may mention the coinage in that metal issued by 
 Timotheus, for the purpose of extricating himself from a 
 pecuniary embarrassment ; this, however, must be considered 
 in the same light as paper-money, and not as a false coin, since 
 its value was secured by the engagements of the general to 
 take it in the stead of silver, and to redeem whatever 
 remained *^^. 
 
 The employment of base kinds of money derives its origin 
 either from fraud, a scarcity of the precious metals, or from the 
 notion that the precious metals are a source of corruption, and 
 that therefore their home circulation must be prohibited. From 
 this latter cause, Plato in his second State imagines, according 
 to the Doric model, a money circulating in the country, and 
 devoid of value abroad {v6/jbi,afMa iiTL^copLov).^ deriving its cur- 
 rency from the countenance of the state ; and together with this 
 another coinage, not in circulation, but kept in the public 
 coffers, of universal currency {kolvov 'EXkrjvLKov vofjucrfia), for 
 the uses of persons travelling in foreign parts, and the carrying 
 on of war"^®. 
 
 This is not mere theory, but was actually put into practice 
 in Sparta*'^^ Even in the time of the Trojan war, the precious 
 metals were well known in the Peloponnese, and the Achaic 
 Spartan Menelaus is particularly mentioned to have possessed 
 both gold and silver ; but the former remained scarce for a long 
 time''' ; whereas silver in the Grecian, as well as in all other 
 
 •'vr Athen. xv. p. GG9 E. Cf. Plu- 
 tarch. Nic. 4. For specimens of his 
 poetry see Aristot, Rhet. iii. 2, Athen. 
 XV. p. 668 E. p. 702 C. X. p. 443 D. 
 xiii. p. 602 C. 
 
 ■*78 See book ii. ch. 24. 
 
 ^'« De Leg. v. p. 742 A. 
 
 ^^^ In the following account I differ 
 somewhat from JNlanso (Sparta, i. 1, 
 p. 162): I leave to the reader to de- 
 cide which of us is the most correct. 
 
 ■'«' See book i. ch. 3.
 
 594 ALTERATIONS IN THE CURRENCY, [bK. IV. 
 
 nations, must have been the most general medium of exchange, 
 as there were few places in which it could not be procured ; in 
 the more early times indeed it was not coined, but circulated 
 in bars of a certain weight. But the Dorians, a people inha- 
 biting a mountainous district, and carrying on no trade, were 
 doubtless scantily supplied with the precious metals ; and since 
 it was a national principle, which existed both by usage and 
 institution, and was afterwards confirmed by what is called the 
 legislation of Lycurgus, to prevent as much as possible all 
 intercourse with other races, they strictly prohibited, at a time 
 long anterior to the coining of money, the use of silver and gold 
 as a medium of exchange, and thus effectually prevented their 
 introduction into the country. If this regulation had not been 
 made in early times, the interdiction of silver and gold could 
 not have been ascribed to Lycurgus ; no modem institution 
 would have been attributed to so ancient a name. The Spar- 
 tans therefore were driven to the use of some other metal as 
 the common medium of exchange, and iron being abundantly 
 obtained in the country, they made use of bars of that metal 
 (o/9eXofc, o/SeXicTKoi), which were stamped with some mark in 
 the iron furnaces of Laconia; while in other countries bars of 
 copper*^'' or silver were current ; whence the obolus or spit, and 
 the drachma or handful, received their names. When after- 
 wards Pheidon abolished the use of metallic bars''^^ and intro- 
 duced coined money, the Spartans also began to stamp their 
 iron in large and rude pieces ; for which purpose they either 
 used, as the author of the Eryxias asserts, lumps of this metal, 
 which were useless for other purposes, such perhaps as are now 
 used for making cannon-balls, or, according to other accounts, 
 they softened the best iron, so as to render it unfit for working, 
 by plunging it when hot in vinegar. 
 
 But when Sparta began to aim at foreign dominion, it had 
 need of a coinage that should be current abroad, for which pur- 
 pose it imposed tributes upon the inhabitants of the islands, 
 and demanded a contribution of a tenth from all the Greeks : a 
 
 "•^^ Plutarch. Lysand. 17. Concern- I the passages quoted in book i. ch. 15. 
 ing the words obolus and drachma see I ^^^ Cf. Etymol. in v. o^eXia-Kos.
 
 CH. XIX.] AS A FINANCIAL EXPEDIENT. 595 
 
 large quantity of the precious metals was also brought into the 
 country by Lysander; and, as we learn from the first Alci- 
 biades of Plato, the wealthy possessed much gold and silver ; 
 as, when once imported, they were never suffered to leave the 
 country. Nevertheless, at this very time the prohibition of all 
 private use of the precious metals was re-enacted, and the pos- 
 session of gold or silver made a capital crime, the government 
 remaining by law the exclusive possessor, as in the ideal state 
 of Plato ; a sufficient proof that this was an extremely ancient 
 custom of the Spartans''^^ ; although it again fell into disuse 
 in the times which immediately succeeded, it being found 
 impossible to maintain so unnatural a prohibition after the 
 advantages of gold had been once made known to the people. 
 
 In this instance the iron money was founded upon ancient 
 usage and moral views. The iron coinage of the Byzantians 
 was of a totally different character, and was similar to the 
 money of the Clazomenians, with this difference that it was not 
 also a certificate of debt. Byzantium, notwithstanding the fer- 
 tility of its territory and its favourable situation for commerce, 
 was for the most part in unprosperous circumstances. The 
 Persian, and afterwards the Peloponnesian war, as well as the 
 wars of Philip, shattered its power and resources; it was 
 engaged in continual warfare with the neighbouring barbarians, 
 and was unable to keep them ofiP either by resistance or tri- 
 butes ; and to crown the other evils of war, they suffered this 
 additional torment, that after having by much trouble and 
 expense obtained an abundant harvest, the enemies either 
 destroyed or carried off the produce of their labour ; until in 
 Olymp. 125, 2 (b.c. 279), they agreed to pay the Gauls a yearly 
 tribute of 3000, 5000, and 10,000 pieces of gold, and at last the 
 large sum of 80 talents, on condition that their lands should 
 not be ravaged*^\ This annoyance compelled them to have 
 
 ^^ The whole of this may be seen ' p. 350, Eryxias 24, cf. Salmas. Usur. 
 by comparing the following passages, p. 320. 
 
 Plutarch. Lysand. 17, Lacon. Apoph- ^«^ Polyb. iv. 45, 4G. Compare Liv. 
 thegm. Lyciirg. 9, 30, Polyb. vi, 49, xxxviii. 16, ITerodian. iii. 2, and others 
 Pollux vii, 105, ix. 79, Xenoph. Rep. concerning the fertility of the country 
 Laced. 7, Porphyr. de Abstin. iii. and its favourable situation. 
 
 2 Q 2
 
 596 
 
 ALTERATIONS IN THE CURRENCY 
 
 [bK. IV. 
 
 recourse to many extraordinary measures for procuring money, 
 and finally, to the imposition of the transit duties, which in 
 Olymp. 140, 1 (b.c. 220), involved Byzantium in the war with 
 Rhodes. 
 
 Among the means resorted to in early times for relieving 
 the financial distresses of the Byzantine state, was the intro- 
 duction of iron money for the home circulation, that the silver 
 might be used for foreign trade and the purposes of war'*^^ It 
 was current in the times of the Peloponnesian war, and bore 
 the Doric name Sidareos, as the small copper coin of the Athe- 
 nians was called Chalcus^^^ As it is stated that it was thin 
 and worthless''^^ it appears to have been only a plate of iron 
 stamped or pressed in upon one side. 
 
 The Greeks were acquainted with no other kind of money 
 but the metallic. There is no necessity for entering into a 
 refutation of the writers*^^ who mention the leather-money of 
 the Lacedeemonians, a fable which we must at once reject, 
 without attempting to remove the testimonies of ancient writers 
 by incorrect alterations'*^**. The same may be said of the 
 leather-money in use among the Romans prior to the reign of 
 Numa: Carthage however made use of a token of this descrip- 
 tion, as we find that some unknown substance of the size of a 
 stater, enveloped in leather and marked with the public seal, 
 supplied the place of metaP\ 
 
 *^^ See Heyne Byzant. p. 11, whose 
 opinion is nearly the same. 
 
 ^87 Aristoph. Nub. 250, Plat. Comic. 
 ap. Scliol. Aristoph. ubi sup. Strattis 
 ap. Poll. ix. 78. [See ^Meineke, Fr. 
 Com.Gr.vol.ii. p.649,775.— Transl.] 
 
 '*^^ AeTTTOV, eXdxiO'Tov rravTOiv Koi 
 (jiavXoTaTov, Schol. Aristoph. ubi sup. 
 Pollux ubi sup. (cf. vii. 105,) Hesych 
 in V. (xibdpeoi. The word eXd^^icrTov 
 does not mean smaUness of size, but of 
 
 value, according to an Attic idiom 
 already remarked by other writers. 
 This iron coin also occurs in Aristid. 
 Plat. Orat. ii. p. 241, vol. iii. ed. Cant. 
 
 •^^^ See the passages quoted by Fis- 
 cher ad Erj-x. ubi sup. 
 
 ^^^ Which is the method adopted by 
 Salmasius with a passage in Pliny, 
 Usur. p. 4G4 sqq. 
 
 ^^ ' Concerning which see Salmasius 
 ut sup. p. 363 sqq.
 
 CH. XX.] OTHKR FINANCIAL EXPEDIENTS. 59/ 
 
 Chapter XX. 
 Other Financial Expedients employed by the Greek States, 
 
 The sacred property was held in much respect by the Grecian 
 repubUcsj and although some instances occur in which they 
 seized the possessions of foreign temples^ as was done by the 
 Phocians and also the Arcadians in 01ympia*^% yet in these 
 cases offence was given not only to the Greeks in general, but 
 even to many of their own fellow-citizens. The Athenians 
 indeed borrowed money from the temples, and Pericles coun- 
 selled them even to remove the golden ornaments of the statue 
 of Minerva, pledging themselves at the same time to replace 
 what they took^^^ : none however but the tyrants, such as Dio- 
 nysius, Lachares, and others, who hesitated not to commit any 
 kind of sacrilege, ever ventured to plunder the property of the 
 temples. But although it may be true that the Greeks, until 
 the period of their final decline, were upon the whole a religious 
 people, yet the confiscation of sacred property is of Grecian 
 origin. Tachus, upon the advice of Chabrias, acquainted the 
 Egyptian priests, that on account of the impoverished situa- 
 tion of the countr}^, it was necessary that some of their oflSces 
 should be abolished. Upon which communication (every 
 priest being unwilling that his own situation should be sup- 
 pressed), they readily furnished him ^vith considerable sums 
 of money; these he exacted not from particular individuals 
 but from their whole number, and allowed all their ofiices 
 to remain as before; he then limited their expenses to a 
 tenth of the former amount, and required the other nine-tenths 
 as a loan until the conclusion of the war. At the same 
 time, by the advice also of Chabrias, he imposed a tax upon 
 houses, a poll tax, a tax upon com, viz., of 2 oboli upon each 
 artabe of corn sold, one to be paid by the seller, the other by 
 the buyer, and an income tax of 10 per cent, upon the captains 
 of vessels, the possessors of workshops, and all other persons 
 
 Xeiioph. Hell. vii. 4, 33 sqq. '^' Thucyd. ii. 13.
 
 598 
 
 OTHER FIXANCIAI. EXPEDIENTS 
 
 [bk. 
 
 IV. 
 
 engaged in trade^^\ Also Cleomenes, the satrap of Alexander, 
 threatened the Egyptians with diminishing the number of the 
 priestSj and, as was the case with Tachus, obtained large contri- 
 butions from them, each one wishing to retain his station*". 
 
 Another favourite measure in pecuniary difficulties, and one 
 well known to the Athenians, was the appropriation by the 
 state of a monopoly of certain commodities, of which I have 
 already spoken in the first book''^^. 
 
 The measure of the tyrant Hippias had an appearance of 
 justice, when in order to raise money he ordered those portions 
 of the houses to be sold, which projected into and over the 
 public street, upon the plea that the street was public property 
 and ought not to be overbuilt : the possessors then repurchased 
 their own property, by which he raised a considerable sum"*®^. 
 The same method was adopted in after times by the Assembly, 
 with the same object and consequence, upon the counsel of 
 Iphicrates"*®^. Another unjust measure was introduced by the 
 same Hippias, who for a moderate sum liberated any citizen 
 from the trierarchy, choregia, and other liturgies, which then 
 pressed heavily upon the other contributors*'®^ 
 
 The Byzantines^"*' in some financial difficulty sold the unpro- 
 ductive lands of the state (by which we are to understand 
 uncultivated and wooded land) in perpetuity, and the productive 
 lands for a term of years, so that in the latter case they in fact 
 only received in advance the rent which would have been annu- 
 ally owing : the same course was pursued with the proj^erty of 
 sacred corporations and the phratrias [OiaawTiKa /cal irarpt- 
 (OTiKo), particularly with that which was surrounded by the 
 estates of private individuals, since the proprietors of these 
 would naturally give a high price for lands thus situated : as a 
 
 *9^ Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 25. 
 
 *" Ibid. 33. 
 
 *^^ See chap, 9. 
 
 **7 Arist. (Econ. ii. 2, 4. 
 
 *^8 Polyaean. iii. 9, 30. 
 
 ^^^ Aristot. CEcon. ubi sup. 
 
 -'"" See Aristot. (Econ. ii. 2, 3, re- 
 /x€i/t; d-q^oaui are public lands which 
 were not connected Avith temples, in 
 
 which case they wonld be oaut. In 
 everything else I have followed the 
 text of Schneider, except that I place 
 a stop after aXaroTTcoXicw, and omit de 
 after rpiTov. There are however pro- 
 bably other false readings in the pas- 
 sage, so that the accoiuit given in the 
 text cannot be relied upon as certain.
 
 CH. XX.] EMrLOYED BY THE GREEK STATES. 599 
 
 compensation for which a portion of the pubUc lands in the 
 gymnasium, the market, and harbour, the places of sale, the 
 sea-fishery, and the sale of salt, were allotted to these corpo- 
 rations. It was also resolved to impose a tax upon jugglers, 
 fortune-tellers, &c., amounting to a third part of their gains ; 
 the money-changing business, which, if the iron coin was in 
 existence, must have been of considerable importance, was 
 farmed out to a single bank; and it was prohibited to buy 
 money from or sell it to any other bank upon the penalty of for- 
 feiting the amount. The rights of citizenship were sold also for 
 money; for whereas the law required that a citizen should be of 
 pure descent both on the father^s and the mother^s side, they 
 were granted to those who were descended from citizens only 
 on one side, upon the payment of 30 minas. Also several resi- 
 dent aliens had lent money upon mortgage, and as the law stood 
 they were unable to take possession of the lands thus pledged, 
 upon which the state granted them the right of holding landed 
 property, on condition that they paid to the state a third part 
 of the principal. In a scarcity of corn they kept back the ships 
 coming out of the Pontus, and when the merchants began at 
 last to complain that they had been detained for the sole pur- 
 pose of selling corn to the Byzantines, a compensation of 10 
 per cent, was allowed to them, which was paid by imposing 
 upon sales a tax of equal amount"*^ 
 
 Chapter XXI. 
 
 Xenophon^s Proposals for Promoting the Welfare of Attica. 
 
 The defects in the Athenian system of finance were not unper- 
 ceived by the acute observers of antiquity; its most striking 
 peculiarity was that the revenue was derived chiefly from foreign 
 contributions : the managers of pubhc aflfairs were indeed aware 
 of the injustice committed against the allies, but they conceived 
 that it was rendered necessarv^ by the poverty of the Athenian 
 people*"*. 
 
 ^'^^ This is the meaning of the ac- 1 has completely misunderstood, 
 count, which Salmasius M. U. p. 219, I ^"'^ Xenoph. de Vectig. init.
 
 600 
 
 XENOPHON^S PROPOSALS FOR PROMOTING [bK. IV. 
 
 It was with this view that Xenoj^hon wrote his Essay on the 
 Revenues^ or the Sources of National Prosperity {Trepl Tropcov), 
 about the close of his life, probably in Olymp. 106, 1 (b.c. 356), 
 after his sentence of exile had been reversed at the instigation 
 of Eubulus ; and it is even possible that he wTote it to serve the 
 cause of Eubulus, as' it exactly coincides with the known opi- 
 nions of that statesman, his desire of peace, and love for the 
 theorica, as well as his attention to the welfare of the people, by 
 which he obtained so great popularity^*^^ 
 
 5°3 That this short treatise was wi-it- 
 ten for Eubulus was first remarked by 
 Schneider, p. 151, vriih great probabi- 
 lity, who has sufficiently disproved the 
 date assigned to it by Weiske (Olymp. 
 89, 3), both in the discussion p. 139 
 sqq. and in the notes. Some observa- 
 tions which I had made in writing 
 with regard to the date of this treatise 
 before the appearance of Schneider's 
 edition mostly agree with the inquiries 
 of this editor, bi;^ as there are some 
 discrepancies between us I will shortly 
 explain my notion. 
 
 It is evident from 2, 7, and 0, I, that 
 Xenophon had returned from banish- 
 ment, nor should Schneider (ad 4, 
 43) have allowed himself to be misled 
 by Weiske into the idea that this trea- 
 tise was written at SciUus or Corinth, 
 from the circumstance of Thoricus 
 being placed to the north, and Ana- 
 phlystus to the south, which might 
 have been as well said in Athens as in 
 the Peloponnese ; concerning this 
 point however I may defer any detailed 
 examination until another place. "We 
 do not indeed know the time of his 
 recal, nor how long he remained at 
 Athens, for he is said to have died at 
 Corinth; but it appears to me that 
 Eubulus could not have had any influ - 
 ence before Olymp, 102, or 103, or 
 even later still 
 
 The following events are mentioned 
 in the course of the treatise, which 
 took place after tlie 100th Olympiad : 
 the voluntary election of Athens to the 
 
 supreme command by sea (5, 6), the 
 voluntary recognition of the Athenian 
 ascendancy over Thebes on the part of 
 the Thebans themselves (5, 7), after 
 the latter had received benefits from 
 Athens; both these events took place 
 in Olymp. 100, | (see book iii. 17, con- 
 cerning both; Schneider, p. 173, states 
 it differently); Sparta having been sup- 
 ported by Athens, allows the latter to 
 maintain its ascendancy as it chooses 
 (5, 7), y^z. in Olymp. 102, 4 (Xenoph. 
 Hell. vii. 1. Diod. xv. 67, see Schnei- 
 der, p. 174), when Athens had sup- 
 ported the Spartans against the supe- 
 rior force of Epaminondas. Athene 
 assists the Arcadians under the Athe- 
 nian general Lysistratus, who does not 
 occur elsewhere (3, 7), an event which 
 cannot have happened before the alli- 
 ance concluded in Olymp. 103, 3 (cf. 
 Xenoph. Hell. vii. 4, 2 sqq. Diod. xv. 
 77> Schneider, p. 150). Also the expe- 
 dition under Hegesilaus, who com- 
 manded at the battle of Man tinea 
 (Diogenes Laert. in A"it. Xenoph. 
 Schneider, p. 150), in Olymp. 104,2; 
 for the expedition against Plutarch in 
 Euboea, on which occasion Hegesilaus 
 was condemned to death, is not here 
 meant, nor did it take place as Schnei- 
 der (p. 138, p. 150) supposes in Olymp. 
 105, 3, but in Olymp. 106, 4 (see book 
 iv. ch. 13). The confusion prevalent 
 in Greece (5, 8), he correctly places 
 (p. 174) after the battle of Mantinea. 
 
 Immediately before the comi)0.sition 
 of this essay a war took place, and a
 
 CH. XXI.] 
 
 THE WELFARE OF ATTICA. 
 
 601 
 
 He begins with considering whether it could not be possible 
 for the Athenians to obtain sufficient subsistence from their 
 
 peace was concluded, by means of which 
 quiet was re-established by sea (4, 40; 
 5, 12, which latter passage has no 
 reference to the duration of the war by 
 land; it is only to be understood of the 
 ill consequences of the past war) : 
 therefore the peace which followed tlie 
 battle of :Mantinea (Olynip. 104, 2) 
 cannot be here intended. It would be 
 better to understand that with Philip 
 in Olymp. 105, 2 (Diod. xvi. 4); it 
 appeal's to me however most probable 
 that the peace which terminated the 
 Social war in Olymp. 106, 1, is meant, 
 as this was the war which had such a 
 disastrous effect upon the finances of 
 Athens (see book iii.ch. 19), and by this 
 peace the security of the sea was re- 
 stored; both facts agree particularly 
 well with 5, 12. 
 
 According to my idea, then, the 
 treatise was written in this year; and 
 at the same time Isocrates laboured to 
 attain the same object as Xenophon in 
 his oration nepl Elprjvijs, and also 
 makes similar complaints of the dimi- 
 nution of the revenue : and moreover 
 the object of the whole treatise being 
 to improve the situation of the Athe- 
 nians without oppressing the allies, 
 agrees exactly with this period of impo- 
 verishment, and with the peace between 
 the Athenians and their allies; and 
 finally, since Schneider (ad Xenoph. 
 Hell. p. 10) has proved that Xenophon 
 Avas alive in Olymp. 105, 4, it is only 
 necessary to lengthen his life by one 
 year. 
 
 On the other hand, Schulz (de 
 Cyrop. Epilog, p. 27), and after him 
 Schneider (p. 139 sq. 1/4 sq.), propose 
 to refer this treatise to so late a date as 
 Olymp. 106, 2, upon the idea that the 
 Phocian war is mentioned in it : it may 
 however, in my opinion, be shown that 
 it was written before that war. The 
 passage in question (5, 9) is as follows : 
 
 — " If the Athenians, without being 
 parties to any war, would, by sendmg 
 ambassadors to the different states of 
 Greece, use their influence to make 
 the temple of Delphi independent, as 
 before, they would have all the Greeks 
 on their side against those who had 
 endeavoured to seize the temple after 
 ' the Phocians had quitted it {eKXtnov- 
 I Tcov Tcov $co<ea)i^)." The Phocians 
 ' had taken the temple of Delphi in 
 Olymp. 106, 2, and since they remained 
 in possession of it during the whole of 
 the Sacred war, the plundering of the 
 sacred property was gradually com- 
 pleted, and they retained possession 
 until the termination of the war in 
 Olymp. 108, 3, which may be seen from 
 Diod. xvi. 23 — 59, cf. Demosth de 
 Fals. Leg. p. 356, 17- Now since 
 Xenophon cannot have written this 
 passage after Olymp. 108, 3, it must 
 refer to some period antecedent to 
 Olymp 106, 2, for it is expressly stated 
 that the Phocians had quitted the 
 temple ; and even if any one were to 
 object that cKkiTrovrcov means, thei/ had 
 become effeminate, they had degenerated, 
 the result remains the same. 
 
 But it may be asked, why are the 
 Phocians mentioned in this place? 
 The state of the case appears to be as 
 follows. The temple of Delphi was, 
 according to the agreement of the 
 Greeks, an independent sacred posses- 
 sion, the chief management of whicli 
 was exclusively vested in the council of 
 Amphictyons and the sacred assembly 
 at Delphi ; but the Phocians were al- 
 ways putting in claims for the direction 
 of this temple, which they aflirmed to 
 belong to them, and that they had even 
 once been in possession of it (Diod. 
 xvi. 23), an assertion which they also 
 strengthened with the authority of 
 Homer (II. u. 518); and these claims 
 were according to Diodorus again
 
 602 
 
 xenophon's proposals for promoting [bk. IV. 
 
 own country; for which purpose, he observes, the land is excel- 
 lent, the climate mild, the soil capable of yielding the best pro- 
 ducts ; and those districts which do not produce corn, are made 
 infinitely richer by the presence of mineral treasures; the sea is 
 also productive, and Attica is most favourably situated for com- 
 merce both by sea and land; and is moreover by her remoteness 
 from barbarian nations relieved from any apprehension of an 
 injury which had been felt by most other states. 
 
 Having thus gone through the natural adva ntages of 
 Athens, he next proposes some plans for improving the general 
 welfare of the country, and creating revenues by which the 
 needy citizens might be maintained; proposals which are 
 neither remarkable for their acuteness or depth, nor capable of 
 being put into practice with advantage, however benevolent and 
 praiseworthy the motives may have been from which they pro- 
 ceeded. The first^''* refers to the resident aliens; these, he 
 says, maintain themselves without receiving anything from the 
 state, and also pay a protection-money; in his opinion the best 
 
 brouf^ht forward in Olymp. 106, 2, 
 when they were assisted by the coun- 
 tenance of Sparta (Diod. xvi. 29). 
 
 In the time of Cimon, the Lacedae- 
 monians had given the temple to the 
 Delphians, that is to say, bad made it 
 independent; but Athens immediately ! 
 afterwards transferred it to the Pho- I 
 cians (Thucyd. i. 112). In the peace j 
 of Nicias (Olymp. 89, 3) independence, \ 
 a native jurisdiction, and freedom from 
 all foreign tribute, were secured by 
 treaty to the sacred property of Del- 
 phi, the temple of Apollo, and the city 
 together with the territory belonging 
 to it (Thucyd. v. 18), as in the pre- 
 ceding armistice the free use of the 
 temple and the oracle had been gua- 
 ranteed, and assistance against sacri 
 lege had been promised to the Delphi- 
 ans (Thucyd. iv. 118); with regard to 
 the first article of this armistice, Sparta 
 particularly invited Boeotia and Phocis 
 to accede to it. The Phocians, how- 
 ever, may have frequently repeated 
 
 their claims, until they at last ceased, 
 as it is stated by Xenophon. 
 
 In Olymp. 106, before the renewal 
 of these claims, the Thebans played 
 the chief part in the council of the 
 Amphictyons ; by their means the Spar- 
 tans were condemned to the enormous 
 fine of 500 talents, and afterwards to 
 double that amount (Diod. xvi. 23, 29). 
 Thebes at that period was still the pre- 
 dominant power, whence Sparta and 
 Athens combined against her, and from 
 their hatred towards Thebes took the 
 side of the Phocians. It is therefore 
 more than probable, particularly since 
 Xenophon speaks so briefly and ob- 
 scurely of the transaction, that it was 
 the Thebans who had endeavoured to 
 obtain possession of the temple, and 
 this before Olymp. 106, 2. Of the 
 claims of the Phocians renewed in this 
 year, and asserted with violence, the 
 author was entirely ignorant. 
 
 *"^ Cap. 2.
 
 CH. XXI.] THE WELFARE OF ATTICA. 603 
 
 of all revenues. For these reasons it is fit that they should 
 receive some farther encouragement: to which end it would be 
 sufficient to relieve them from some degrading liturgies, that 
 were of no advantage to the community, and from serving as 
 hoplitee; for the state would be more benefitted if the armies 
 were composed of citizens, than if they were mixed with 
 Lydians, Phrygians, Syrians, and other barbarians; and again, 
 it would be honourable to the Athenians to rely in battle rather 
 upon themselves than upon foreigners. He also proposes that 
 those who on application might appear worthy, should be 
 allowed to serve in the cavalry, and should receive permission 
 to build houses, in order to cover the empty spaces within the 
 walls; also that protectors of resident aliens {/jLerooKocpvXaKes) 
 should be appointed, and rewards given to those who brought 
 more persons of this class into the city; which would have the 
 double effect of increasing the good-will of the aliens actually 
 resident, and of bringing all refugees under the protection of 
 Athens. 
 
 If the Athenians followed the counsels of Xenophon, the 
 prosperity of Athens would have been in imminent danger of 
 being destroyed by internal causes. The citizens would in that 
 case have singly carried on a perpetual war, and have been 
 swept away in battle; while the resident aliens passed their life 
 in security: and although the latter might have borne some 
 share in the dangers of war, would not all the noble families 
 have gradually become extinct? The citizens would have been 
 compelled to give up their occupations, and submit to an entire 
 loss of property, while the resident ahens, having obtained pos- 
 session of all commerce, all industry, and at last of the land, 
 would have become sole proprietors of all wealth at the expense 
 of the Athenians. They would also have received the rights of 
 citizenship in greater numbers than was actually the case, and 
 the state thus have suffered the severest injury. Nothing con- 
 tributed more to the destruction of Athens, than the gradual 
 extinction of the descendants of the ancient Cecropidse; and a 
 foreign race, enriched by banking and other usurious practices, 
 destitute of all noble motives, and bent only upon momentary 
 gain, forced themselves into the rights of citizenship, and the
 
 G04 XENOPHON^S PROPOSALS FOR PROMOTING [bK. IV. 
 
 adnuiiistration of the state. If the Athenians had deUberately 
 sanctioned this course of pohcy, they must either have been 
 beyond measure philanthropic and benevolent, or been willing 
 to sacrifice their real prosperity for the purchase of a trifling 
 benefit. A comparatively large number of resident aliens may 
 indeed have been advantageous for commerce, for industry, and 
 the public revenue; but higher considerations of policy could 
 not permit that they should be favoured in the degree proposed 
 by Xenophon. 
 
 The unquestionable advantages, he proceeds to say, which 
 Athens possessed for commerce*'^*, arose not only from its 
 favourable situation, its magnificent and commodious harbours, 
 but also from the excellence of its coin, which could always be 
 exchanged with profit; so that the merchants of Attica, instead 
 of being, like the traders of other places, obliged to export 
 commodities for the purpose of barter, had the option of carry- 
 ing out money. The first suggestions that our author makes 
 for the improvement of trade are, that prizes should be 
 appointed for the commercial court, to be awarded to which- 
 ever member should give judgment with the greatest rapidity 
 and fairness: the object of this proposal was afterwards efi^ec- 
 tually gained by the introduction of the monthly suits^^®: also 
 that particular honours should be given to the merchants and 
 the masters of vessels, in order that with the increased number 
 which these distinctions would attract, the amount of the 
 exports and imports, of the sales, of the wages of labour, and 
 the public duties, might be augmented^. He also recommends 
 a particular plan, which required a contribution of money, from 
 a conviction that the Athenians, who had been so often taxed 
 
 ^^^ Xenoph. chap. iii. I Thus also Aristotle Polit. i. 3, ^(vtxio- 
 
 ^"^ See book i. ch. 9. I repay yap yiyvop,evT]s rrjs l3oT)6ias tu> 
 
 ^ [The sentence in the original is, eladyearBai wv eVSeeTy Ka\ eKTrefXTreiv wv 
 drJiXov on TocrovTco av ttX(7ov koI elad- ^ iiiK^ovu^ov, i^ thdyKTjs f] tov vofiicr/Jia- 
 yoiTO Koi i^dyoLTO Kai eKTreixnoLTO Koi . tos eTTopiadr) xpr^aLS. And again vii. 
 TTooXoTro Koi [xto-du(f)opo'LTO Ktii reXecr- 6, to. nXeovd^ovra tcop ycyuofxevuiv e'/c- 
 (fiopoiri. The last editor, Diudorf, pro- Tre/jLyj/aadai. vii. 12, toIs dnu rrjs dciXda- 
 poses to expunge the words kcu i^d- (tijs iT€p.iTop.€vois. Thucyd. iv. 26, 
 yoiTo, comparing i. 7> rrpoadyeTdi 8e I ecnrefineiv rd airla, iv. 30. (t7tov ecr- 
 av delrai kuI dnuTrefxneTat a ^ovXerai. I Treixneiu. — Transl.]
 
 CH. XXI.] THE WELFARE OF ATTICA. G05 
 
 for the maintenance of fleets and armies, and had expended 
 large sums without any sure prospect of benefit resulting to the 
 state, and with a certainty of never recovering their money, 
 would willingly contribute to this undertaking. He proposes 
 to build public inns and warehouses, in addition to those already 
 in existence, for the entertainment of captains of vessels and 
 merchants, as well as son:ie conveniently situated market-houses; 
 and to purchase some public trading-vessels, which, like other 
 property belonging to the state, were to be let out for hire upon 
 the production of sufficient security. The author supposes that 
 the profit upon this speculation would amount to 3 oboH a day; 
 so that the subscribers would obtain a very high per centage 
 upon their shares: a subscriber of 10 minas would receive 
 nearly 20 per cent. [vavriKov a-)(^ehov eTrLTrefiirrov), exactly 
 180 drachmas for 360 days; and of 5 minas more than the 
 third part of the principal [eTrlrpiTov vavriKov). The larger 
 number however would receive annually more than their 
 original contributions; for example, subscribers of 1 mina 
 nearly double that sum, and this in their native country, which 
 appears to be of all others the safest and most desirable method 
 of investment. Foreigners also might be expected to contri- 
 bute, if in return for their contributions they were registered 
 among the eternal benefactors of the Athenians, an honour of 
 which some kings, and tyrants, and satraps, might wish to 
 partake. 
 
 In all this exposition there is nothing obscure, but nearly 
 the whole is without any foundation in reality. Xenophon 
 supposes unequal contributions, according to the diiferent 
 amount of property, agreeable to the principles of a property 
 tax, but an equal distribution of the receipts for the purpose 
 of favouring and aiding the poor; the reason which induced 
 him to fix upon the rate of 3 oboli, appears to have been that 
 this sum was just sufficient for the most scanty subsistence ; 
 the common daily wages were likewise 3 oboli, as were also the 
 salaries, for example, the pay of the judges and the assembly; 
 but the payment of the wages of the judges is no more in 
 question than the wages of sailors; what Xenophon is speaking 
 of is an income annually arising upon each share, either equal
 
 606 
 
 XENOPHON^S PROPOSALS FOR PROMOTING [bK. IV. 
 
 to or exceeding the interest of loans on bottomry^"'. Where 
 however was the security that the undertaking would produce 
 3 oboli a day to each subscriber? This most essential point is 
 entirely wanting to these airy speculations of the Athenian 
 philosopher. 
 
 The most important and explicit part of this short Essay is 
 the chapter upon the silver mines ^''^ According to Xenophon, 
 the Athenian mines were inexhaustible: "they have/' he says, 
 '^ been worked from time immemorial, and yet to how small a 
 portion of the hill in which the metal is found have the works 
 already extended ! nor is the place which contains the silver 
 narrowed by the further progress of the mining, but is evidently 
 increased as more of the soil is exposed. Even at the time 
 when the number of persons labourhig there was at the highest, 
 there was enough, and more than enough, employment for all. 
 And at the present time no proprietor of slaves in the mines 
 reduces their number, but, on the contrary, keeps increasing it 
 to the utmost of his power. The value of silver,^' he proceeds 
 to say, " is not diminished by an increase in the quantity, for 
 the uses to which it can be applied are manifold, and no one is 
 satisfied with the amount which he actually possesses. Gold,'' 
 he allows, " is equally useful with silver; this, however, I 
 
 5«7 Salmasius M. U. chnp. 1, falls 
 into innumerable eiTors, by consider- 
 ing the triobolon to be the pay of the 
 dicasts, from which however he ex- 
 cludes the Pentacosiomedimni and the 
 Thetes (the latter of whom were the 
 very persons who had the chief share 
 in it) ; but, not to mention that to 
 allow of this interpretation it must 
 have been to rptoi^oXov, the whole ex- 
 planation is so senseless, that it is un- 
 intelligible how a rational being could 
 have hit upon it. Of a part of this 
 confused investigation, Heraldus, his 
 victorious adversary, justly says (Ani- 
 madv. in Salm. Observ. iii. 15, 17), 
 " Somnium est hominis harum rerum, 
 etiam quum vigilat, nihil scientis" He- 
 raldus (ibid. ii. 20, 2), refutes the ab- 
 
 surdities of Salmasius, but under- 
 stands it just as absurdly himself to 
 mean the pay of the seamen (^S 3), and 
 considers vavriKov to mean salarium 
 nauticum{% 4), whereas it is evidently 
 to be taken, with Salmasius, for money 
 lent upon sea security, which Schneider 
 has also observed against Weiske. 
 Who would agree to give a sum of 
 money, exceeding indeed that contri- 
 buted by others, in order to receive a 
 share in a salaiy given for labour on 
 board a vessel, without any distinction 
 being made as to the different amount 
 of tlie deposit, and this only three 
 paltry oboli, which he might have had 
 without contributing anything ! 
 "^^ Chap. 4.
 
 CH. XXI.] THE WELFARE OF ATTICA. 607 
 
 know/^ he says, " that when it appears in large quantities, it 
 becomes itself cheaper, and makes silver dearer. Now although 
 the state sees that many private individuals grow rich by their 
 mines, who by hiring out the slaves working in them obtain a 
 net profit of an obolus a day for each slave, it does not imitate 
 their example : it might, however, secure a permanent revenue, 
 by purchasing public slaves, until there were three to each 
 Athenian (that is, about 60,000) ; and by letting these, like all 
 other public property, upon proper security. In this proceed- 
 ing there would be no danger of loss ; for if the slaves were 
 marked with the public seal, it would not be easy to steal 
 them: nor would the state be injured by the competition of 
 other slave-proprietors.^^ He then proposes first to purchase 
 1200; "from the profits arising from these the number might 
 in five or six years be raised to 6000^"% which would produce an 
 annual income of 60 talents ; of this sum, 20 talents might be 
 applied to the purchase of fresh slaves, and 40 used for other 
 expenses. When the number shall have been brought fo 
 10,000, the income will be 100 talents; but that it would be 
 possible to procure and maintain a number far greater than 
 this, is proved by what happened before the war of Decelea. 
 It might also,'^ he then suggests, " be advisable to undertake 
 new works, in which there would be some hazard of loss, from 
 the various success experienced in searching for ore; as this 
 uncertainty deterred many private individuals from purchasing 
 new mines from the state.^^ In order, therefore, that the 
 danger might not fall upon single persons, he proposes to give 
 an equal number of slaves to the ten tribes; that each tribe 
 should open new mines, and that they should bear the good or 
 ill success in common ; and former experience did not justify 
 the expectation that all the trials would be unsuccessful. He 
 also observes, that it would be safer for private persons to form 
 associations of this kind; an arrangement which was subse- 
 quently adopted. 
 
 Now it was impossible that all these proposals should attain 
 their object. In the first place, it is inconceivable that, in 
 
 ^^ See above book i. ch. 13.
 
 608 xenophon's proposals for promoting [bk. IV. 
 
 addition to the private slaves, 60,000 public slaves could have 
 continued for any length of time to work the mines with profit, 
 but either the state or individuals must soon have been losers. 
 That Xenophon^s belief in the inexhaustibility of these mines 
 was a mere delusion, has been proved by subsequent experi- 
 ence ; not to mention that in bad seasons the dearness of corn, 
 joined to the imperfection of the smelting processes known to 
 the ancients, would have precluded any profitable employment 
 of capital in this business : and in fact many proprietors did 
 cease working, and the mining was at length discontinued^^ ^ 
 
 Xenophon then properly remarks, that it would not be 
 prudent to attempt all these schemes at the same time, both 
 from the large amount of contributions requisite, and the 
 necessary result of purchasing any considerable number of 
 slaves, viz., that their quality would be bad and price high. 
 Whereas, if they were tried in succession, the profit derived 
 from one undertaking might be applied to the execution of 
 another. "But,^' he proceeds to say, "if it should be supposed 
 that on account of the property taxes raised in the preceding 
 war, it would be impossible to obtain any contributions from 
 private individuals, the expenses of the administration for the 
 coming year might be defrayed from the smaller revenues, as 
 had been done in the last war, and the surplus which would be 
 created by peace, the encouragement shown to the resident 
 aliens, and the improvements in trade, might be applied to 
 these undertakings. Nor would the arrangements proposed be 
 useless in case of war, for by reason of the increased population, 
 the state would be enabled to augment the number of sailors 
 and soldiers : the mines again, being already protected by 
 fortresses, might be easily put in a state of greater security; 
 and partly on account of their situation, partly from the 
 difficulty which an enemy would find in obtaining provisions 
 there, and his inability to profit by the ore, they would be but 
 little exposed to attack. Lastly, the state would not only 
 derive a greater revenue from the slaves, but with the increased 
 
 •''"* Tlie proofs of all these assertions may be seen in my Dissertation upon 
 the Mines of Laurium.
 
 CH. XXI.] THE WELFARE OF ATTICA. 609 
 
 numbers of those dwelling near the mines, a large income 
 would be obtained from the market, from the public buildings, 
 and several other sources ; and the land in their neighbourhood 
 might acquire as great a value as that around the city; and not 
 only this, but the citizens would be made more tractable, 
 regular, and warlike, by the increase of the public prosperity, 
 as they would receive daily wages for exercising in the 
 gymnasia, for garrison duty, military service, &c." 
 
 Among all his schemes and recommendations, the exhorta- 
 tion to peace''' is the only one which is entirely unobjec- 
 tionable; it is not, however, peculiar to him, for the same 
 proposal was made by Isocrates at the same period, and is 
 perpetually inculcated by the orators, who sometimes repeat it 
 at very unseasonable moments. "The prosperity of Athens 
 wilV^ in his opinion, " be thus raised above that of any other 
 state; for,^^ he continues, "would not ship-captains and 
 merchants flock thither ? where would those who are rich in 
 the various products of the earth, together with all w^ho are able 
 to gain their livelihood either by talents or money, handicrafts- 
 men, and sophists, and philosophers, poets, and those who 
 minister to the productions of poetry, with all who are desirous 
 to hear or to see the spectacles and splendour of Athens, both 
 sacred and profane, as well as persons w^hose object it is to buy 
 and sell with dispatch — where would all these obtain their 
 several ends so well as at Athens ? The ascendancy or empire 
 over the Greeks would be more easily preserved by mildness 
 and peace, than by wars and violence. In war not only are 
 several branches of revenue deficient, but all the money paid 
 into the treasury is consumed in defraying the expenses of it. 
 And,^' he urges, " it may be seen that the revenue has always 
 fallen off in time of war, and that the whole receipts were 
 immediately consumed. And if any one were to ask me," he 
 says, "whether, if another nation commits an injury against 
 the state, I should dissuade any revenge of the wrong, 
 my answer would be no: but I must remind you, that it 
 would be far more easy to punish the offenders, if we have 
 
 5'' Chap. 5.
 
 fnO XENOPHOn's proposals. [bK. IV. 
 
 committed no injury ourselves; for in that case they would 
 have no ally/^ 
 
 " If these proposals are put in practice'*' %^' he continues to 
 say, " we shall obtain the good will of the Greeks, an increase 
 of security, and a more lasting fame ; the people will be well 
 supplied with food, the rich be relieved from the expenses of 
 war; from the abundance and plenty that would exist, the 
 festivals will be celebrated with greater splendour, the temples 
 will be restored, the walls and docks repaired, and the priests, 
 the senate, and j)ublic officers, and knights, receive their former 
 dues. If these proposals should meet with the public approba- 
 tion, I would counsel you,^^ he says, ^^to send messengers to 
 Delphi and Dodona, and consult the gods as to the expediency 
 of these plans : for if they are done with the favour of the 
 divinity, it is to be expected that the measures of the state will 
 always have a fortunate issue.^^ This pious conclusion recon- 
 ciles the reader with his author, notwithstanding the many 
 weak points in the work itself; at the same time, it is hardly 
 possible to forgive him for not advising the Athenians to be 
 more sparing in their festivals, instead of which he flatters them 
 with the prospect of increasing the expense and magnificence. 
 This wish, however, proceeds from the most sincere conviction 
 and earnestness; Xenophon^s own disposition coincided with 
 the inclinations of his patron, and the pernicious tendencies of 
 the Athenian people. 
 
 Chapter XXII. 
 General Vieiv of the Financial System of Athens. 
 
 If we now take a general survey of the financial system of 
 Athens, which more or less resembled that established in all 
 the other Grecian repubhcs, with the exception of Crete and 
 Sparta, we shall perceive that in many parts it was both 
 planned and executed with acuteness and judgment; and that 
 even its imperfections were so blended with its excellences, that 
 
 ''■' Chap. 6.
 
 CH. XXII.] FINANCIAL SYSTEM. 611 
 
 by their removal, liberty, the source of all public virtue, would 
 have been endangered. 
 
 Although the Greeks were neither poor nor indifferent to 
 riches, the quantity of the precious metals in circulation was 
 proportionally far less than in the European states of later 
 times. Much therefore was effected with little money; and as 
 property returned high profits, individuals could contribute 
 largely to the state without infringing upon their capital. 
 Moreover the financial system of the Athenians was in itself 
 simple; their views seldom reached beyond the service of the 
 current year, unless indeed the command of some extraordinary 
 resources, such for example as the tributes, led to the adoption 
 of an extended plan of operations. To peculation and the 
 embezzlement of money they were frequently indifferent; and 
 from ignorance of the limited extent of their resources, they 
 incurred great expenses, and soon became involved in diffi- 
 culties. The numbers of the popular assembly embarrassed 
 their statesmen in the management of public affairs, and pre- 
 vented the execution of prompt or decisive measures. A large 
 portion of the public money was through piety devoted to the 
 worship of the gods; much of it also was expended upon monu- 
 ments which will form a lasting record of their elevated 
 thoughts, their heroic deeds, as well as of their consummate 
 taste for the arts. 
 
 But though they executed the most splendid works which 
 have ever been conceived by the mind of man, their resources 
 could not be altogether appHed to such noble objects: the 
 craving wants of the lower order of their citizens also required 
 to be satisfied; who by salaries and donatives in time of peace 
 had become accustomed to indolence, and to the idea that the 
 state was bound to maintain them: and as by these means the 
 lowest persons were placed sufficiently at their ease to attend to 
 the administration of the state, the influence of the democracy 
 was insensibly extended. Their statesmen were always endea- 
 vouring to discover some method by which the mass of the 
 people might be enriched and supported out of the public 
 revenues, rather than by individual industry and prudence; as 
 the commonweal was considered as a private possession to be 
 
 2 R 2
 
 612 GENERAL VIEW OF [BK. IV. 
 
 enjoyed in common, the proceeds of which were to be distributed 
 among the members who composed the state. And yet it 
 w^ould appear that donations and salaries are nowhere less 
 necessary than for states in which slavery is established. The 
 degradation of the greater part of the inhabitants enables those 
 who are free to obtain their subsistence by the labour of the 
 slaves ; and it is thus that they have sufficient leisure to attend 
 to affairs of state; whereas in countries in which slavery does 
 not exist, the citizens having to labour for their subsistence are 
 less able to employ themselves in the business of government. 
 Plato, therefore, in his sketch of a perfect state, proposed that 
 the governing class should be maintained at the public cost. 
 The pay of the soldiers, which was early introduced in Athens, 
 is less objectionable; but the expenditure incurred on this, as 
 well as on other accounts, far exceeded the internal resources 
 of the state. Extravagance at home, the expense of the mili- 
 tary operations, and the maladministration in their foreign pos- 
 sessions, gave rise to the oppression of their allies, whose 
 dependant and tributary condition drew down upon the tyrant 
 state the hatred of Greece. In order to maintain her power 
 which was derived from foreign resources, Athens heaped injus- 
 tice on injustice, and endeavoured by oppression and terror 
 to assert that dominion, which indeed no state in Greece had 
 so just a claim to, and to which she had, as it were, been led 
 and pressed onward by the natural course of events. As how- 
 ever the galling restraints imposed upon the subject states 
 could necessarily endure only for a time; and as a voluntary 
 combination among the Greeks, such as that against the Per- 
 sians, could never have been permanent, the Athenian state, 
 and w^ith it the rest of Greece, must in the end have been 
 overthrown, even if Philip of Macedon had not risen up 
 against it. 
 
 Of the different revenues of the state, the custom duties 
 were the least oppressive, as having been imposed with suit- 
 ableness and moderation. On the other hand, the immense 
 fines, although they produced a large income to the state, were 
 a constant inducement to unjust decisions. The power of con- 
 fiscating property was in the hands of wild and thoughtless
 
 CH. XXII.J THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM. 613 
 
 demagogues^ a dreadful scourge upon the rich and great; par- 
 ticularly if the proceeds were forthwith distributed among the 
 people. The liturgies^ although of great utility, were injurious j 
 because they were not arranged according to any fair propor- 
 tion. Patriotism, religion, enthusiasm, and not less than these, 
 ambition, stimulated individuals to make great sacrifices for the 
 state. The three first however gradually became extinct; while 
 the latter, being applied to base instead of to worthy ends, exer- 
 cised only a pernicious influence. 
 
 In the history of the Greeks, we do not wish to undervalue 
 their greatness, or to detract from their noble qualities: we 
 allow that much was better than in modern states, better than 
 in the Roman empire when sunk in corruption ; better far than 
 under the oppressive and degrading despotisms of the East: but 
 much also was worse than in our times. It is only a partial or 
 superficial view which discovers nothing but ideal perfection in 
 antiquity. The eulogy of past times, and the unquahfied cen- 
 sure of everything contemporary, are the results frequently of 
 perverted judgment, or perhaps of a narrow and disdainful 
 selfishness, which considers the heroes of antiquity to be the 
 only associates worthy of its own imagined greatness. There 
 are however parts of the Grecian history less brilliant than 
 those which are commonly brought into view. Even in the 
 noblest races of Greece, among which the Athenians must 
 without doubt be reckoned, depravity and moral corruption 
 were prevalent throughout the whole people. Although their 
 free governments, and the small independent communities into 
 which the different nations were divided, may have produced 
 an intense and constant excitement, they were at the same 
 time the causes of innumerable disturbances; and, if we except 
 those exalted minds, which found sufficient support within 
 themselves, we shall in vain search for that abundance of com- 
 fort and charity which a purer religion has poured into the 
 hearts of mankind. The Greeks, with all the perfection of their 
 works of art and the freedom of their governments, were more 
 unhappy than is usually believed; even in the times of their 
 glory, they bore within themselves the seeds of that destruction 
 which was sooner or later destined to befal them. The forma-
 
 614 FINANCIAL SYSTEM. [bK. IV. 
 
 tion of large states into monarchies, which has limited the 
 sphere of individual action, and given a greater degree of 
 stability to the principles of government, appears to be an 
 essential advance in the condition of the human race ; provided 
 that there be also present that energy of individual character, 
 that free and daring spirit, that implacable hatred of oppres- 
 sion and the arbitrary power of rulers, which so distinguished 
 the Greeks. For without these w^e should in vain hope to 
 escape that destruction in which the states of Greece were 
 ultimately overwhelmed.
 
 A 
 
 DISSERTATION 
 
 ON 
 
 THE SILVER MINES OF LAURION 
 
 IN 
 
 ATTICA\ 
 
 § 1. Situation of the Laurian Mines, and their 7'elation to 
 the neighbouring Towns, 
 
 If we consider the advantages which Athens derived from the 
 mines of Laurion, a prominent station should undoubtedly be 
 assigned to them among the numerous gifts of nature' with which 
 the country of Attica was favoured^. The means which they 
 afforded for the profitable employment of capital served at the 
 same time to enrich many private individuals and to maintain 
 large numbers of slaves (who, when occasion required, might 
 be used in manning the fleets^) ; and the state derived from 
 them an income, which, as being productive of injury to no one, 
 an ancient writer^ justly considers as the best source of public 
 revenue. If we except the happy situation of the country, the 
 freedom of the constitution, and the mental superiority of the 
 inhabitants, no one circumstance perhaps contributed so much 
 to the prosperity of the state as the possession of these mines. 
 
 " From the Memoirs of the Berlin : x^oj/os-. 
 
 Academy for the years 1814 and 1815, 
 p. 85—140. 
 
 ^ iEschylus (Pers. 235), mentioning 
 the resources of the Greeks, says, 
 upyvpov TTT^yrf ns avrois icrri, drjaavpos 
 
 ■^ Cf. Xenoph. de Vectig. 1, 5. 
 
 3 Cf. Xenoph. nt sup. 4, 42. 
 
 ■* The author of the Introduction to 
 the second book of the (Economics 
 falsely attributed to Aristotle.
 
 616 
 
 SITUATION OF LAURIAN MINES^ AND 
 
 The power of Athens depended on her fleets, her wealth upon 
 foreign commerce. It was the produce of the silver mines 
 which first enabled Themistocles to found the naval force of his 
 country; and nothing so much promoted her trade as the purity 
 of her silver coin, which, while many other states of Greece 
 circulated a metal current only at home, was every where 
 exchanged with profit\ This wise arrangement was doubtless 
 in great measure occasioned by the possession of silver within 
 their own territor)\ 
 
 The mountain, or rather hill, in which the silver mines were 
 situated, was called Laurion or Laureion, but never Lauron; 
 the mines themselves Laureia or Lauria; and the district Lau- 
 riotike^ Its height is inconsiderable; Attica is of less eleva- 
 tion from Hymettus down to the coast, so that whenever the 
 mountains of this country are spoken of, Brilessus, Lycabettus, 
 Parnes, Corydallus, Hymettus, Anchesmus, and others are 
 named^, but never Laurion, although the latter was no less 
 remarkable than any of the others. Hobhouse^ describes it as 
 a high and abrupt hill, covered with pine trees and abounding 
 in marble; Stuart also recognised in Legrina and Lagriona 
 near Sunium, the name Laurion, which has also evidently been 
 
 * Xenoph. ut sup. i. 3, cf. Aristoph. 
 Ran. 730—736, Polyb. xx. 15, i6. 
 
 " Aavpiov, and \avpeiov, both either 
 with or without opos, frequently occur, 
 the former in Thucyd. ii. 55, where see 
 the commentators, Pausanias i. 1, 
 Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 361, Suidas in v. 
 yXav| tTrrarai, Hesychius in v. yXavKes 
 Aavpi(OTLKal, Schol, yEsch. Pers. 237, 
 and Liban. xx. ; the latter in Herod, 
 vii. 144, Andoc. de Myster. p. 19, 20, 
 where it is falsely accented Aavpelov 
 (a MS. has however in both places I 
 instead of EI.) In Thucyd. vi. 91, 
 the reading varies in the manuscripts. 
 The first method of writing this word 
 is confii-med by the derivative Aavpioi- 
 TiKos, with a short Iota, in Aristoph. 
 Av. 1106. Plutarch (Nic. 4,) calls the 
 district AavpioiTiKrjy where Reiske in- 
 
 correctly proposes to read AavpeayriKTJ. 
 Aavpeia for the mines occurs in Hesy- 
 chius, and consequently Aavpia was 
 also in use, but that Aavpov was used 
 for Aavpwu cannot be believed on the 
 credit of the same grammarian (in v. 
 Aavpov). 
 
 ^ Strabo ix. p. 275, (ed. Casaub. 
 1587,) Pausan. i. 32, Plin. Nat. Hist. 
 iv. 11, &c. 
 
 ^ Travels in Albania, &c. vol. i. p. 
 417. It might be inferred from his 
 account that the silver ore ran into 
 marble ; this is however uncertain : 
 the passage in Stuart afterwards re- 
 ferred to is Ath. Ant. vol. iii. p. xiii. 
 Compare the passage from the Un- 
 edited Antiquities of Attica, quoted in 
 note 16.
 
 THEIR RELATION TO NEIGHBOURING TOWNS. 6l7 
 
 preserved in the names Lauronoris, Mauronoris, Mauronorise 
 [Aavpiov opo^). According to his statement, it is an uneven 
 line of mountains full of exhausted mines and scorise, stretch- 
 ing from Porto Raphti to Legrina: and there forming the Pro- 
 montory called Mauronise: it appears that the highest part, as 
 laid down in the maps, is near the south-west coast; for accord- 
 ing to Pausanias in the commencement of his work, this moun- 
 tain is seen by a person sailing from Sunium to the Piraeus, in 
 the direction of the desert island of Patroclus: but the silver 
 mines stretched from coast to coast in a line of about sixty 
 stadia from Anaphlystus in the south-west, to Thoricus on the 
 north-east sea^ To what distance they reached downwards to 
 Sunium and upwards to Hymettus, is unknown. In the age of 
 Xenophon, the extent of the mines was continually increased, 
 as new spots abounding in ore were discovered^": but to none 
 of the bordering countries, either towards the sea, or towards 
 the main-land, did any veins of silver extend: Attica alone, 
 says Xenophon, had received this gift of heaven' \ 
 
 If WQ may judge from the dense population of the whole 
 country, it seems evident that the particular district of the 
 mines must have been very populous, and necessarily included 
 several villages, which served for the habitation of the labourers: 
 and by these the situation of the mines might perhaps be more 
 accurately ascertained. Laurion itself was indeed neither a 
 harbour, as is stated by Meletius in his geography, and by 
 Lauremberg in an old map wnich has now become useless'^; 
 nor a demus, as Corsini has correctly observed against Meursius 
 
 ^ Xenopli. ut sup. 4, 44. In a letter I (Whaler, Travels, p. 424), is meant, 
 of Francis Vernon, who had travelled which lies farther northwards near 
 in Greece, translated by Spon from the ' Zoster, not far from the harbour of 
 Philosophical Transactions (Travels, j Phalerum, and according to Wheler is 
 vol. iv. p. 301), the wi'iter observes ; the Phaura of Strabo, as the situation 
 that he had seen an island between | shows. It is however more probable 
 Phalerum and Sunium, called Phlehes I that salt was found there than ore. 
 {(pXe^es), where the Athenians once ^" Ibid. 4, 3. 
 had mines. Lest it should be sup- " Ibid. 1, 5. 
 
 posed that a place near Anaphlystus is '^ Melet. Geogr. p. 349, the old edi- 
 intended, where the veins ran across tion, Lauremberg Grsecia Antiqua, p. 
 to an island, I remark that La Phlega 23, in Gronovius' Thes. A. Gr. vol. iv.
 
 618 SITUATION OF LAURIAN MINES, AND 
 
 and Spon'^; and the grammarians '% who call it a place in Attica, 
 probably mean something more than the mountain ; for it is 
 very possible that there were public buildings erected in some 
 particular spot, which, together with other houses and foundries, 
 composed the town of Laurion. 
 
 Anaphlystus was one of the chief demi; Thoricus was in 
 early times one of the twelve independent towns, and after- 
 wards became a demus, although by Hecatseus and other later 
 writers it is called a town : in Mela^s time, however, it was only 
 a name, for, according to the probable conjecture of Chandler, 
 it sank at the same time with the mines. Leroy, in the year 
 1754, was driven by contrary winds into a port near a place 
 which, according to his account, was still called Thoricus. He 
 describes it as situated in a plain bounded with hills, into which 
 to the south (according to our maps to the south-west) projects 
 a mountain which he recognised as Laurion ^^ Chandler, on 
 the other hand, considers the modern Cerateia (which Meletius 
 calls a village {Kcofir]), and which, according to Hobhouse, con- 
 tains about 250 houses) as Thoricus, without however having 
 been upon the spot. Wheler, who suggested another notion, 
 had visited Cerateia, a town which, fifty or sixty years previous 
 to his arrival, before it had been destroyed by corsairs, had been 
 a considerable place, and had possessed certain privileges; but 
 from its situation, this cannot be Thoricus. Spon is entirely 
 mistaken in considering the modern Porto Raphti as the ancient 
 Thoricus. The statement of the modern English writers is 
 undoubtedly true: viz. that the harbour now called Theriko, 
 situated seven miles to the south-east of Cerateia, was the 
 ancient Thoricus; as is now evident since the publication of 
 
 ^^ Meursius de Pop. et Pag. Spon, ' Stephan. Byzant. in v. QopiKos, PHn. 
 Travels, vol. iii. pai't ii. p. 153, Cor- I Hist. Nat. iv. 1 1, Mela ii. 3, iv. 7, 
 sini Fast. Att. vol. i. p. 248. Even j Wheler, Travels, p. 448, Chandler, 
 Sigonius, who always shows judgment. Travels, chap. 33, Leroy, Les plus 
 although he has left many inquiries beaux Mouumens de la Grece, ed. 2, 
 uncompleted, omitted Laurion in the vol. i. p. 3. Alost of the passages upon 
 list of the demi. Thoricus have been collected by Meur- 
 
 ^* Suidas and Photius. sins (de Pop. et Pag.); cf. Duker ad 
 
 '* Strab. ix. p. 274, Hecataeus ap* Thucyd. viii. 95.
 
 THEIR RELATION TO NEIGHBOURING TOWNS. 
 
 619 
 
 the remaining part of Stuart^s work'^ The country near that 
 place is mentioned as the particular district of the mines ^^. 
 -^schines, the orator, also mentions an ipyacrrripcov or com- 
 partment in the silver mines of Aulon, which place was so 
 called from its forming a long and narrow valley resembling a 
 channel' ^ 
 
 A mine situated near Maroneia is mentioned by Demos- 
 thenes^*: the identity of the name of this place with that of the 
 Thracian Maroneia, a colony of the Chians, either arose acci- 
 dentally, or from the name being carried over from Attica to 
 Chios, and thence being introduced into Thrace; to which sup- 
 position the hero Maron, who is celebrated in the Odyssey, and 
 from whom the Thracian town is said to have received its name, 
 does not furnish any well-founded objection. Mines or work- 
 shops at Thrasyllus are also mentioned by both the above-cited 
 orators. This place received its name from a monument of 
 Thrasyllus (as Harpocration informs us), and must have been 
 situated in the district of Maroneia^"; for in Demosthenes, the 
 mine near Thrasyllus, as may be gathered from the context, is 
 the same with the mine at Maroneia. 
 
 Lastly, in several maps of Attica, the demus called Besa is 
 placed in the district of the mines, nearly in the middle between 
 Thoricus and Anaphlystus*', the position of the place being 
 
 ^^ Spon, Travels, vol. iii. part ii. p. 
 135. Stuart ut sup. Hobhouse, Tra- 
 vels, vol. i. p. 411, 420. The unedited 
 Antiquities of Attica, comprising the 
 Architectural Remains of Eleusis, 
 Rhamnus, Sunium, and Thoricus, 
 London, 1817, p. 57- 
 
 ^7 Plin. xxxvii. 5, Schol. ^sch. ut 
 sup. 
 
 1^ iEsch. c. Timarch. p. 121, Suidas 
 in V. av\a>v€S, Lex. Seg. p. 206, AvXav 
 Toiros TTjs WTTiKrjS KoXeTrai, eneidr) eVt- 
 fjLr]Kr]S Koi arrevos as avXm eoiKcvai. 
 
 ^» C. Pantaenet. p. 907, 17, and 
 thence the argument of the same ora- 
 tion, Harpocration, Suidas, Photius, 
 Lex. Seg. p. 279. 
 
 2" iEschines ut sup. calls the district 
 eVi Gpao-u^Xo), Demosthenes ut sup. p. 
 
 973, 29, eTTt QpaavWov ; Harpocration 
 however in v. eVi QpaavXXcp reads 
 QpaavXXco in the latter place, although 
 from the interpretation eVi tS QpacrvX' 
 Xov p.urifj,aTi the genitive might seem 
 preferable. Meursius Lect. Att. v. 
 30, accuses Harpocration of confound- 
 ing the bath of Thrasyllus with this 
 monument; besides this pm-ely arbi- 
 trary assumption, he confesses that lie 
 has incorrectly referred this place to 
 Amphitrope, to which he was misled 
 by the false derivation of the words in 
 -/Eschines now long since corrected. 
 
 ^^ As is laid in the map by Philip 
 Argelatus in the works of Sigonius, 
 vol. V. and in Kitchen's map in Chan- 
 dler's Travels.
 
 620 
 
 SITUATION OF LAURIAN MINES, AND 
 
 fixed on the authority of a passage of Xenophon. According 
 to this writer, there were, on both coasts, fortifications at Tho- 
 ricus and Anaphlystus : and if a third fort were placed upon 
 the highest point of " Besa," the two first would be thus con- 
 nected, and on the alarm of an hostile attack, every person from 
 the mines would easily be able to take refuge in one of the 
 walled places". The meaning of this writer is indeed too 
 obscurely expressed to allow of our drawing any sure inference; 
 the reading moreover is not sufficiently certain, and the term 
 Besa is ambiguous: the latter word may either be the proper 
 name of a place, or signify a low ground covered with bushes; it 
 is however by no means improbable that the district received 
 the name of Besa from this particular circumstance, and that 
 this demus should be here sought for ; besides which the name 
 Besa is, according to Stuart, still in existence. It may be 
 observed, that by the iQrm fortifications we are not to under- 
 stand long walls, but single castles, in which the labourers 
 might take refuge; the connexion spoken of by Xenophon 
 was caused by the contiguity of the three places, from which 
 the intervening country might be commanded. The works at 
 Thoricus and Anaphlystus are the fortifications at those places. 
 
 ■^^ Xenoph. ibid. 4, 43 sqq. from 
 which I will extract the following 
 words : ecrrt iiev yap drjTTOv nepl ra 
 fieraXKa ev rfj npos fxea-TjplBpiav daXdrTt] 
 reT;^os' ev ^ Ava(p\vaT(o., ecrri 8e iv rfj 
 TTpos apKTOV relxos iv OopiKW' une^eL 
 8e ravTOf ott' aXXT^Xcoi^ dp-Cpl to. e^rjKovra 
 (TTadia. El ovv Koi ev pecra tovtcov 
 yevoiTO eni rco v'^Xotutco ^r^acrr^i rpi- 
 Tov epvpa^ (jvvrjKOL t (not as is com- 
 monly read crvvrjKOLT) av ra epya els ev 
 e^ cnravTOiv tuiv Teixo>v Kal e'l ri alaoa- 
 voiTO TtohepiKOV, ^paxp av e'lt] eKaarco 
 els TO da(PaXes u7ro;(a)pj}crai. Brjaarjs 
 was first edited by Stepliauus ; if the 
 borough is meant, ev Brjarj would be 
 the most natural expression ; but if 
 only a low hill covered with bushes, it 
 would seem to require the article ttjs 
 ^r)(Ta-r)s. A'^alesius (ad Harpocrat. in v. 
 ^r)ar)Ls) is of opinion that the borough 
 
 is meant. Strabo ix. p. 293, observes 
 that the borough was written Brjcra 
 and not Bi]oraa, which is confirmed by 
 inscriptions ; but there can be no doubt 
 that the appellative was originally 
 wi-itten in tlie same manner, and that 
 the ancient form was retained in the 
 proper name, while in the otlier word 
 it soon disappeared. Schneider, whose 
 edition of this work of Xenophon did 
 not appear until after the completion 
 of this Essay, has received Brja-ijs into 
 the text : Chandler and Hobhouse (ut 
 sup. p. 420), also assume that Besa is 
 here mentioned. [The author says in 
 his collection of Greek Inscriptions, 
 vol. i. p. 290, " De Besa nunc addenda 
 est eximia Issei aiictoritas de Pyrrhi 
 Ilered. p. 27, postquam Bekkerus ex 
 libris restituit verum Bj^cra^e." Orat. 
 Att. p. 34.— Transl.]
 
 THEIR RELATION TO NEIGHBOURING TOWNS. 621 
 
 which on account of their importance as military posts had been 
 converted into castles. Thoricus had been placed in a state of 
 defence by the Athenians in Olymp. 93, 1 (b.c. 408), perhaps 
 with a view to the protection of the mines": that Anaphlystus 
 was a fort (ret;^©?) is also observed by Scylax in his Peri- 
 plus; and as Sunium had been fortified in Olymp. 91, 4 
 (b.c. 413)^*, these places were entirely defended from attacks 
 by sea. 
 
 Invasions by land, against which Xenophon^s new fort was 
 to be erected, were attended with great difficulties; for, accord- 
 ing to the remark of this military writer, the enemies^ troops 
 would be forced to pass by the city; and if their numbers were 
 small, they would be cut off by the cavalry and guards in the 
 country; while, by coming in large force, they would both 
 expose their own territory, and be unable to maintain their 
 ground from want of provisions: and even if they were masters 
 of the mines, they would derive no more benefit from the silver 
 ore, than from mere stones. In the second year however of 
 the Peloponnesian war Olymp. 87, f (b.c. 430), the Spartans 
 and their allies advanced in the district of Paralos as far as 
 Laurion*'; and although it is not mentioned that they obtained 
 actual possession of the mines, yet the working of them would 
 probably have been suspended, even if the enemy had not 
 advanced so far. At a later period the fortifying and the conti- 
 nued occupation of Decelea by the Spartans, which was main- 
 tained by the advice of Alcibiades, deprived the state of the 
 revenues from Laurion^^, as the regular working of the mines 
 must probably have been thus impeded ; the slaves too eloped, 
 and the connexion with the capital was interrupted by the long 
 protracted warfare carried on within the country. 
 
 23 Xenoph. ITellen. i. 2, 2. I ^^ Ibid. ii. 55. 
 
 ^* Thucyd. viii. 4. I ''^ Ibid. vi. 91.
 
 622 PERIOD DURING WHICH 
 
 § 2. Period during which the Mines were worked. 
 
 That the silver mines of Laurion had been worked in remote 
 antiquity, is certain from the testimony of Xenophon^^; no one 
 indeed ever attempted even to say at what time the ore was first 
 extracted. 
 
 The working of mines had a very early origin both in the East 
 and in Egypt : for as the precious metals generally lay near the 
 surface of the soil, they would naturally attract the attention 
 even of the mere savage wanderer. Man indeed appears to 
 have been originally endowed with an instinct analogous to that 
 possessed by the bee and the beaver; an instinct subservient to 
 the ends of social union (to which man, as x\ristotle truly says, 
 is determined by the command of nature), yet at the same time 
 not incompatible with those higher endowments which are 
 requisite for the establishment of civil society; with the advance 
 of civilization however its use and existence gradually dis- 
 appeared, and the original acuteness in the mental perceptions 
 gave place to a more simple state of these functions; in the 
 same manner that the instinct of animals and the quickness of 
 their senses are diminished by taming. But, next in order to 
 husbandry and the keeping of cattle, the most essential requisite 
 for a social life is the possession of metals. Without therefore, 
 incurring the charge of fanciful speculation, we may infer that, 
 as mankind discovered the food suited to their wants by the 
 instinct of nature and not by accident, in the same way also 
 they were led to seek after metals and to perceive their uses. 
 This supposition is equally removed from two opposite and 
 improbable suppositions, either that the human race was in its 
 earliest stages in a state of brutish savageness, or that it was 
 possessed of a high degree of illumination and wisdom; between 
 which extremes the truth is to be looked for. 
 
 Whether the art of mining in general had so remote an 
 origin in Greece is in itself another question. It is certain 
 however that many mines in this country were first worked by 
 
 De Vectig. 4 2.
 
 THE MINES WERE WORKED. 623 
 
 inhabitants of Asiatic nations, as for instance those of Thasos 
 by the Phoenicians. The Athenian silver mines indeed appear 
 to have been opened long after the emigration which probably 
 took place from Egypt. Whatever Xenophon may say of the 
 early period at which they were worked, the scarcity of silver in 
 the time of Solon proves that no systematic or artificial process 
 of mining could at that time have been established. But in the 
 time of Themistocles, before Xerxes' expedition against Greece, 
 when at the advice of that statesman a large fleet was fitted 
 out from the revenues of the mines for the purpose of the 
 ^ginetan war, they must have been worked with considerable 
 activity. 
 
 In the age of Socrates we find indeed that a large number of 
 labourers were employed in the mines by private individuals ; 
 but the public revenue derived from them was much lower than 
 in earlier times'^; and consequently the amount of silver 
 obtained was less considerable: notwithstanding which, Xeno- 
 phon in his Essay upon the Revenues, entertains such exag- 
 gerated notions of the excellence of these mines, that he appears 
 to have believed that they were inexhaustible ; for he states it 
 as an important point that of the district which contained the 
 silver a small part only was worked out, when compared with 
 that which remained, although the works had been going on 
 from time immemorial ; that after innumerable labourers had 
 been employed there, the mines always appeared the same as in 
 the time of their ancestors ; and that everything indicated that 
 the number of labourers in them could never be increased 
 beyond the means of profitable employment. The number of 
 the labourers however, according to his own statement, had 
 already begun to diminish. The majority of the mine proprie- 
 tors were at that time beginners^ ^; the working of the mines 
 therefore appears to have nearly ceased before the last years of 
 the life of Xenophon (during which the Essay in question was 
 written), either from the frequency of the wars, or because the 
 poverty of the ores had prevented the proprietors from obtaining 
 a profitable return. 
 
 28 Xenoph. ISIemor. Socrat. iii. G, 12. | '^^ Xenoph. de Vectig. 4. 2, 3, 25, 28.
 
 G24 PERIOD DURING WHICH MIXES WERE WORKED. 
 
 In the age of Philip which immediately succeeded, there 
 were loud complaints of unsuccessful speculations in mining ; 
 and subsequent experience showed that the silver mines could 
 be so far exhausted as to leave no hope of an adequate profit. 
 In the first century of the Christian era, Strabo^" remarks 
 that these once celebrated mines were exhausted ; for, as the 
 farther working of them did not yield a sufficient return, the 
 poorer ore, which had been already removed, was smelted, 
 together with the scoriae from which the metal had been imper- 
 fectly separated in former times. Pausanias in the latter^ half 
 of the second century after Christ makes mention of Laurion, 
 with the melancholy addition that it had once been the seat 
 of the Athenian silver mines. 
 
 § 3. Ores and Minerals found in the Laurian Mines, 
 
 The ore from which the silver v\as obtained is generally called 
 silver earth {dpyvplris yrj or simply apyvplnsy^', but that by 
 this we are not to understand soft earth, may be collected from 
 an expression of Xenophon, who says that the enemy could 
 make no more use of the ores from these mines than of stones. 
 The word earth in Greek is of very general application, and 
 may include ores even of solid stone : the Romans also applied 
 the same term to silver ore^*. 
 
 The quality of the ore in the mines of Laurion is nowhere 
 expressly stated : it is possible however to throw some light 
 upon the subject by a few incidental accounts. As the works of 
 Laurion are always called silver-mines, and as neither lead, 
 copper, or any other mineral is ever mentioned, it is evident 
 that, in early times at least, they must have afforded ores 
 extremely abundant in silver, more particularly as the ancients, 
 from their imperfect knowledge of chemistry, could not make 
 
 ^° ix. p. 275. Plutarch. deDef. Orac. v. fUToXka) is an inaccurate expres- 
 c. 43. I sion, for earth and sand have not by 
 
 ^' Thus Xenophon, compare Pollux any means the same import in tlie 
 vii. 98, ^Apyvplris afipos in tlie gram- | lan^iage of tlie ancients. 
 marians (as e. g. Lex. Seg. p. 280, in | ^^ Plin. xxxiii. 31.
 
 ORES AND MINERALS IX THE LAURIAN MINES. 625 
 
 use of ores in which the proportion of silver was inconsiderable. 
 This is also proved by the fact of the ore being called silver 
 earthy and not lead or copper earth. Mines of the precious 
 metals are usually more productive nearer to the surface of the 
 soil than at a greater depth, and the quantity of silver contained 
 in many ores diminishes in proportion as they recede from the 
 surface : therefore when the miners penetrated farther into the 
 interior of the mountain, it is not impossible that they met with 
 ores of inferior quality; which partly explains the diminution in 
 the profit already alluded to. The ore of these mines appears 
 moreover to have occurred for the most part in thick layers, 
 since otherwise the whole mountain would not have been so far 
 excavated that nothing was left but supports for the purpose of 
 safety; whereas ores in which the silver composes the larger 
 part of the substance usually occur in veins. 
 
 Other less distinct traces, moreover, would seem to prove 
 that a considerable part of the ore was lead ore containing a 
 portion of silver. It is mentioned by Spon^% that old men 
 residing in that district remembered a lead mine, which the 
 inhabitants had suffered to fall into neglect, from fear that the 
 Turks might think proper to work it, and by that means subject 
 them to inconvenience. " Lead," he states, " is brought from 
 the neighbouring places of a more perfect quality than the com- 
 mon kind, as the goldsmiths in the process of purification find 
 some silver in it." To this account, however, the statement of 
 Wheler^"' is most strikingly opposed, who in a journey from 
 Porto Raphti along the north-eastern coast of Attica to Sunium, 
 within a short distance from the latter place, arrived at a small 
 mountain, where, according to his statement, a large quantity of 
 copper had been formerly obtained, and the Athenian gold- 
 smiths, as was said, found silver in it: this was not, however, 
 allowed to reach the ears of the Turks, lest the grand seignior 
 should make the inhabitants slaves for the purpose of working 
 
 ^ Travels, vol. ii. p. 2C5. i Wheler, as well as Chandler. Hob- 
 
 ^^ Ut sup. Hobhouse (ut sup. p. 420), house likewise saw the heaps of cin- 
 
 also speaks of copper in this dis- ders. 
 
 trict, but evidently only copying from I 
 
 2 S
 
 626 
 
 ORES AND MINERALS FOUND 
 
 the mines. The ashes which he there remarked confirmed him 
 in his belief of this statement: to which he adds the strange 
 remark, that whether there once was in that place a city called 
 Laurion he knows not: if, however, it did exist, it was assu- 
 redly built upon the advice of Xenophon, who proposed the 
 erection of a fortress in this place; that probably, however, it 
 was nearer to the sea, where there is an harbour for the car- 
 riers who go to Macronisi, the ancient Helena. Both travellers 
 evidently speak of the same fact ; if both are right, we must 
 suppose that there was a mixture of ores, in which copper and 
 lead, as is frequently the case, were combined : the mention of 
 emeralds at Thoricus, of which I shall afterwards speak, may 
 indeed be taken as an indication of the existence of copper ore, 
 although the hill of which Wheler speaks was further inland, 
 about the place where Besa is placed. Hobhouse saw at 
 Athens a specimen of the ore found a short time previously, but 
 what it was he does not mention. Clarke, who, from his know- 
 ledge of mineralogy, was best fitted to give a solution of the 
 difficulty, could learn nothing of the silver mines^\ 
 
 Spon^s statement, however, receives confirmation from an 
 account in an ancient author. According to the Second Book 
 of the CEconomics^^ (which, although not the production of the 
 writer to whom it is attributed, is not for that reason undeserv- 
 
 '' Travels, vol. ii. part ii. p. oTJ. 
 The quotations from ancient writers 
 made by Walpole in the note on that 
 passage are of very little importance : 
 he also states that the Athenians ob- 
 tained copper from Laurion ; probably 
 however from a misconception of So- 
 phocl. CEd. Col. 57. 
 
 ^^ IIvdoi<\ris\\dT]ya'ios* Adr]V(iLois avv- 
 €^ov\eva€ TOP fioXv^dov tov ck tcov 
 TvpLOiV TTapaXu^^dueiv napa twv ISicotcov 
 Tr)v ttoXlv axTTrep evrcoXoui/ dldpa^fiov, 
 fira rd^avra avTols Tipr)v e^adpdvfxov 
 ovTO) ncoXelv. For rd^avra avTols 
 should eitlier be read rd^arrti' atrois or 
 Ta^avras avTovs. The correction which 
 I have adopted was first proposed by 
 Sylburgius ; but it is not necessary 
 
 with the same commentator to write 
 TOV Aavplov or Aaupe/ou, as the mines are 
 called Aavpeia and consequently also 
 Aavpia. Salmasius, de Usuris, cap. 9, 
 p. oof), silently follows the true read- 
 ing: Tvpfxidav, the conjecture of Ca- 
 merarius, does not deserve any notice. 
 Reitemeier, in his learned Treatise 
 upon the Arts of Mining and Founding 
 among the Ancients (vom Berghau und 
 Hiittenweseu der Alten, Guttingen, 
 1 785), has too hastily considered the 
 lead from Tyre as of Spanish origin. 
 See p. 18. [Mr. Wordsworth, Athens 
 and Attica, p. 208, conjectures e'/c Ta>v 
 dpyvp'ioiv^ which ought rather to be 
 dpyvpficov. — Transl.]
 
 IN THE LAURIAN MINES. 62/ 
 
 ing of credit), Pythocles the Athenian counselled the state to 
 buy up the lead from private individuals, at the usual price of 
 2 drachmas, and having obtained a monopoly, to fix the price 
 at 6 drachmas. According to the common reading, this lead 
 is supposed to come from Tyre; but would it be possible for 
 any person in such a small country as Attica to propose a 
 monopoly of an article of import, which was not necessarily 
 consumed in any large quantities ? Again, if imported lead were 
 meant, it would have been mentioned that the state was to buy 
 it of the merchants, and not of private individuals. How much 
 more obvious would it have been to obtain a monopoly of some 
 domestic product of extensive consumption : if Athenian lead was 
 consumed to any great amount in foreign countries, the state 
 would have made a considerable profit, so long, at least, as the 
 buyers did not find a market where they could purchase on 
 more advantageous terms. If, moreover, it is remembered how 
 easily the singular expression rbu Sk tcov Tvplwv may be altered 
 into the more commodious one of tov Ik tcov Aavptcov, this pas- 
 sage must be considered as a complete proof that the mines of 
 Laurion supplied a considerable quantity of lead; which for 
 evident reasons I will not endeavour to confirm by the fact that 
 litharge is particularly mentioned as coming from the Athenian 
 silver foundries. 
 
 Besides lead, and perhaps copper, ores containing zinc were 
 also found at Laurion, as will be shown presently. 
 
 By some grammarians these mines are called gold mines, 
 without any mention of silver^^; and the Scholiast of Aristo- 
 phanes and Suidas explain the owls of Laurion as gold coins. 
 I do not mean to deny that Athens issued gold coins, and the 
 owl would probably have been the device upon them; but there 
 can be no doubt that the staters or tetradrachms, as well as 
 other silver coins which bore this device, were commonly called 
 owls of Laurion. The Scholiast of Aristophanes'^ in another 
 passage also mentions that both gold and silver were found at 
 Laurion ; but the testimony of so uncertain a witness cannot 
 
 37 Hesycb. in v. Aaipeia, Schol. Aristoph. Eq. 1091, Suidas in v. y\ai> 
 InraTai. '' Eq. 361. 
 
 2 S 2
 
 628 ORES AND MINERALS FOUND 
 
 have any weight against the silence of all good writers. Mele- 
 tius also asserts (perhaps on the authority of these writers) 
 that between Sunium and Cerateia, and therefore somewhere 
 near Thoricus, there existed mines of gold and silver. An 
 amusing story preserved in some grammarians relates that the 
 Cecropidae, misled by a false report, once ascended the moun- 
 tain Hymettus with an armed force, for the purpose of obtain- 
 ing possession of the golden sand guarded by the warlike ants, 
 and that after many troubles they returned home, without effect- 
 ing their object^ ^ ; a tale of equal authority with the statements 
 above noticed. If indeed some small portion of gold was mixed 
 with the silver ore of Laurion, it was far too inconsiderable in 
 quantity to be extracted profitably, with the imperfect know- 
 ledge of the art of smelting possessed by the ancients. 
 
 The emeralds, the cinnabar, and the sil of Attica, deserve 
 also to be mentioned. 
 
 Of twelve kinds of emerald, which is the number assumed 
 by the ancients, three were particularly valued, and would at 
 this time be considered genuine emeralds : the other nine were 
 stones resembling emeralds, and, according to Pliny, were all 
 found in copper mines; the best of these were the Cyprian, 
 which, as well as those of Chalcedon, even Theophrastus calls 
 spurious; a fortiori then the same exclusion may be applied to 
 the Athenian, among the defects of which Pliny particularly 
 instances their dead colour, and that their green tint was 
 gradually bleached by the light of the sun. They were found 
 in the silver mines of Thoricus ; if therefore Pliny is accurate 
 in his account, as he had just before stated that all the nine 
 spurious kinds were found in copper mines, it follows that at 
 Thoricus copper ore was present in the silver mines*". 
 
 Of cinnabar {Kcvvd^apt), with the exception of that brought 
 from India, which belonged to the vegetable kingdom, there 
 were, according to Theophrastus"', two species, the natural. 
 
 ^^ Harpocration and Suidas in v. I *° Concerning the emeralds see Plin. 
 Xpva-oxoflov, and the passage of Eu- xxxvii. 17, 18, Theophrast. de Lapid. 
 
 buhis tlie comic poet there quoted. § 46, ed. Hill. 
 
 [See Meineke, Fr. Com. Qr. vol. iii. I *' Ut sup. § 103, 104, avTo(f)ves and 
 
 p. 215. — Traxsl.] I TO KGT^ epyaaiav.
 
 IN THE LAURIAN MIXES. 629 
 
 found in Spain, which was hard and stony; and the artificial, 
 chiefly made above Ephesus. The material from which the 
 latter was prepared was a shining sand of the colour of scarlet 
 or cochineal {kokkos), which was comminuted and washed down 
 to a fine powder. Callias the Athenian, who worked silver 
 mines at his own expense, found some of this sand in his mines, 
 which he ordered to be collected, thinking from its shining 
 appearance that it contained gold. Finding himself deceived 
 in this expectation, but still admiring the briUiancy of the sand, 
 he hit upon the method of preparing cinnabar from this sub- 
 stance, in Olymp. 93, 4 (b.c. 405)''^ Consequently, although 
 this artificial cinnabar was not made of quicksilver and sulphur, 
 it was nevertheless real cinnabar : which fact, as far as I am 
 aware, has never been pointed out. For although Theophrastus 
 distinguishes it from the natural, it cannot be inferred that he 
 means the spurious kind, since immediately afterwards*^ he gives 
 it to be understood that it was not some peculiar substance 
 manufactured by an artificial process, but that the preparation 
 of art endeavoured to imitate the work of nature. In the same 
 place he treats of the preparation of quicksilver from cinnabar, 
 without remarking that it was necessary for this purpose to have 
 the natural kind; if, however, quicksilver could be obtained 
 from cinnabar prepared artificially, it was in fact the very sub- 
 stance which we call cinnabar. Pliny"* also reckons the prepa- 
 ration discovered by Calhas as the genuine minium or cinnabar, 
 the true test of which was, as he states, its scarlet colour, which 
 distinguished it from the minium secundarium, an inferior pro- 
 duction of the silver and lead foundries. 
 
 But the most complete proof that the artificial cinnabar was 
 derived from an ore of quicksilver is furnished by a comparison 
 of Vitruvius with the two writers already mentioned. The 
 cinnabar above Ephesus was prepared artificially according to 
 the method discovered by Callias: Pliny, upon the authority of 
 a passage of Theophrastus, states with greater accuracy that 
 
 *-^ Theophrast. ut sup. Plin. xxxiii. j *'^ § 105. 
 37. Cf. Corsiiii Fast. Att. vol. iii. "* xxxiii. 37, 40. 
 p. 202.
 
 630 ORES AND MINERALS FOUND 
 
 the Cilbian plain was the precise spot of its manufacture; now, 
 according to Vitruvius**^, cinnabar was at this very place pre- 
 pared, in the manner mentioned by Theophrastus, from a 
 material which consisted in part of cinnabar dust, and partly of 
 indurated quicksilver ore, with intermixed drops of quicksilver 
 in a liquid state. According to Vitruvius, quicksilver flowed 
 from the ore itself when exposed to the action of heat. The 
 only distinction then between cinnabar and the sand from which 
 the artificial cinnabar was prepared, was, that in the latter a 
 foreign substance, as it were, was combined, which was sepa- 
 rated by washing (in the same manner that in the inflammable 
 cinnabar ore of Idria the cinnabar is intimately combined with 
 inflammable schist) : whereas Theophrastus only calls that 
 natural cinnabar, which was found in an unmixed state. It may 
 be also mentioned, that the minium secundarium of Phny, which 
 was far inferior to the artificial cinnabar of Callias, must have 
 contained cinnabar; for a species of quicksilver, although of an 
 inferior kind, was prepared from it, which, to distinguish it 
 from the genuine argentum vivum, was called hydrargyi'us*^. 
 
 Besides the quicksilver ore, which, agreeably to what has 
 been just said, was found at Laurion, there occurred a substance 
 called Sil, which was likewise used as a material for dyeing. 
 The Romans obtained it from diff'erent places; among others, 
 within their own territory, about twenty Roman miles from the 
 city; but that which came from Attica was most esteemed''^ 
 If a vein of it was discovered in the silver mines, it was followed 
 in the same manner as one of precious metal; since it was much 
 used for white-washing and also for painting, to which latter 
 purpose it first was applied by Polygnotus and Micon. In the 
 time of Vitruvius it could no longer be procured from Attica. 
 Pliny, who wrote at a later date, speaks of it as an article 
 still in use, either transcribing the statements of earlier writers, 
 as Salmasius supposes, or perhaps because supplies had been 
 again obtained. Salmasius''^ indeed asserts that sil was the 
 same substance with cinnabar; an error into which he was led 
 
 " vii. 8, 9. I "7 Vitruv. vii. 7, PHn. xxxiii. 6C, 57- 
 
 '•*' See Plin. xxxiii. '62, 41, and there *^ Salmas. Exercit. Pliu.p. 1157 sqq. 
 Hai-douiu. , I ed Par.
 
 IN THE LALRIAN MINES. 631 
 
 by combining the account of Callias having collected a sand, 
 with the fact that so great value was attached to the veins of sil 
 in the Athenian mines; and which, when once adopted, he 
 endeavours to support by other still weaker arguments. The 
 editor of Theophrastus irepl XlOcov assents to his opinion with- 
 out examination'^ But were it not sufficient that Vitruvius 
 and Phny treat of sil and cinnabar in totally different places, 
 the statements with regard to the two substances are in them- 
 selves irreconcileable : cinnabar was sold at Rome for 70 ses- 
 terces a pound, and the Attic sil for only 2 denarii or 8 
 sesterces: the artificial cinnabar was prepared from solid ore or 
 from sand, while sil is described as slime or mud {limus), that 
 is to say, soft earth'". 
 
 Vitruvius, whom Salmasius accuses of error, affords us the 
 clearest explanation with regard to the nature of sil; for he 
 states that its Greek name was M)(pa, i. e. ochre. Theophras- 
 tus'^ distinctly calls w-^pa an earth, which he opposes to sand; 
 and Dioscorides and Zosimus the chemist particularly mention 
 the Athenian ochre'^. Sil and cinnabar were therefore totally 
 different substances, and by the first (of which the distinguishing 
 marks, as stated by ancient authors, are very obscure) can 
 hardly be understood anything but an iron ochre, of a yellow 
 colour, sometimes of a darker, sometimes of a brighter shade. 
 I may also remark the great improbability of Salmasius^s charge 
 against Pliny and Vitruvius, that they confounded sil with cin- 
 nabar, the former having been found in the neighbourhood of 
 Rome; and farther, that there is no necessity for tracing the 
 Greek origin of the name sil, as Italy possessed the same sub- 
 stance (though in less perfection) within her own territory. 
 
 It may be also observed, that the Te(o<pdvLov, which was the 
 subject of the oration of Dinarchus against Polyeuctus, was 
 probably a pit from which sil was extracted. The gramma- 
 rians expressly state that it was a yellowish earth (777 ^avOorepa) 
 used by painters; "perhaps,'^ they add, "raddle {/jll\to<;) or 
 potters' clay, or else earth for other purposes" .^^ Ameipsias 
 
 *» Ad § 103. 
 
 *" Plin. xxxiii. 40. 
 
 *' De Lapid. § 71. 
 
 ^^ Dioscorid. v. IOC, Zosimus ap. 
 Salinas, iit sup. 
 
 ^■^ Etyni. in v. yecofpavelou, Lex. Seg.
 
 632 
 
 MINING PROCESSES 
 
 the Athenian comic poet had also made mention of raddle pits", 
 which is by no means inconsistent with what has been said. 
 Farther accounts with regard to the minerals in the Laurian 
 silver mines I have not been able to find". 
 
 § 4. Mining Processes used at Laurion. 
 
 Of the various artificial processes of mining in use at Laurion a 
 better account could be given, if what the followers of Aristotle 
 had written concerning metals and mines were still extant. 
 Theophrastus in his book upon Stones, refers to his earlier 
 work upon Metals, in which they had been treated of in detail; 
 according to the List of Theophrastus's Works by Diogenes, it 
 consisted of two books. It is frequently called the Metallicon, 
 and undoubtingly ascribed to Theophrastus; in one passage, 
 however, in which it is cited by Pollux, he adds, "whether the 
 book is the production of Aristotle or Theophrastus;" although 
 in another place he simply mentions Theophrastus. Probably 
 the treatise was first included among the works of the Stagirite, 
 and was subsequently, after critical inquiries, correctly assigned 
 to his pupil. Although the fragments preserved are incon- 
 siderable, they show that this great natural philosopher had 
 paid a particular attention to mining or the art of founding^\ 
 
 p. 227, Ilarpocr. Hesycli. and Suidas 
 in V. y€a>(f)dviov, and the commentators. 
 Dionys. Halic. in Yit. Dinarchi. The 
 y€(ocf)dviov in the island of Saraos, of 
 which Ephorus treated (Harpocr. in v. 
 yeaxpdviov, Pollux vii. 199, cf. Marx. 
 Ephor. p. 262 sqq.) differed from this. 
 It might indeed appear from Pollux 
 that Dinarclius had written upon the 
 ye(ocf)duLov of Samos; but the words 
 vnep (ov 6 Aeivupxos Xeyet, which are 
 wanting in a manuscript, are evidently 
 the production of a later hand; and the 
 speech of Dinarclius against Polyeuctus 
 referred to an offence committed by 
 the latter in Attica, and not in Samos, 
 although this island was at tliat time 
 settled with Athenian cleruchi. I con- 
 tent myself with merely pointing this 
 
 out; the space does not admit of a 
 more detailed examination. 
 
 ^■^ Pollux vii. 10, Phot, in v. ^tXro)- 
 pv)(^ia : TOTTos iv co piXros opixracTaf 
 ovToas 'Afietylrias. Cf. Ilesych. in v. 
 IxiXTcopuxLa, and Eustath. ad II. b 637. 
 
 ^^ As a circumstance worth remark- 
 ing, it may be mentioned, that of the 
 Attic honey, which was much esteemed, 
 that made in the neiglibourhood of the 
 silver mines held the second rank after 
 that of Uymettus, and bore the name 
 of uKdnuiarov or aKanvov, Strabo ix. p. 
 27'>. Compare Plin. Nat. Hist. xi. 15. 
 
 *^ Theophrast. de Lapid. ^^ 3, rrepX 
 pev ovv Tiou peraWevopevciiv iv liXXois 
 TfdfcoprjTiii : in this sentence the ex- 
 pression peraXXevopeva should be re- 
 marked, which was intentionally chosen.
 
 USED AT LAL'RION. 633 
 
 His successor, Straton of Lampsacus, treated of the machinery 
 used in mining {Trepl twv /JLeraWtKcov /jajx^vrj/ndrcovy, by 
 which we are to understand all the artificial contrivances. 
 Atheneeus^^ also mentions a Metallicoti of an unknown author, 
 named Philon; where it is evident from the context that among 
 other subjects mention was made of the Egyptian mines, which 
 had been described by Agatharchides and Diodorus. 
 
 The information given by Reitemeier in his ingenious trea- 
 tise on the "^Arts of Mining and Founding among the Ancients/^ 
 concerning the system of labour in the Athenian mines, though 
 superior to what he has said upon the other branches of the 
 art, has by no means rendered a more circumstantial investiga- 
 tion superfluous. It will therefore be necessary that the subjects 
 connected with this question, and especially the system of 
 founding, should be considered independently of that essay^^ 
 
 The mines at Laurion were worked either by shafts {(ppeara^ 
 putei) or adits (vttovo/jlol, cu?iei); and by neither of these two 
 modes of working did they, in the time of Xenophon, arrive at 
 the termination of the ore^°: for the chambering of the mines 
 timber was probably imported by sea^', which according to 
 Pliny was the case also in Spain®^. Hobhouse^^ mentions that 
 one or two shafts have been discovered in a small shrubby plain 
 
 as /xeVaXXoi/ properly signifies a mine, i ^'^ Diog. Laert. v. 59. This is the 
 Alexander of Aphrodisias (see Menage true name of the book ; the various 
 ad Diog. Laert.) also calls the treatise readings and Menage's attempt at 
 irepl Tcou ^€TaXX€vofjL€v<ov ; it does not emendation are equally to be rejected, 
 however by any means follow fi-om ^^ vii. p. 322 A. 
 this, that it did not embrace the sys- ! ^^ The treatise of the Abbot Pas- 
 tem of mines and foundries. Diog. chalis Karj^ophilus de antiquis metalli- 
 Laert. v. 44, and from hira Suidas in fodinis (Vienna, 1757) I have not been 
 v. Gedc^paoToy, have the general name able to refer to; from his Essays de 
 TTfpi /xeraXXo)!/, as in later times fieraX- Marmoribus Antiquis and de Thermis 
 \ov signified both mine and metal, Hercv.huds et de Thermarum usu, little 
 without any distinction. The other , however can be expected, 
 places in which the book is quoted are i ^° Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 26. 
 Olympiodorus ad Aristot. Meteor iii. , ^' Demosth.c. Mid. p. 568, 17. 
 6 nevTOLTOVTov ('AptaTore'Kovs) fiadTjTrjs ; ^^ xxxiii. 21. 
 
 eypayp-ev Id'ia nepl eKdcrrov peraXXov, ^^ Ut sup. p. 417, the following is 
 Pollux vii, 99, X. 149, Harpocrat. in v. the entire passage: "One or two of 
 Kfyxpewi/, and thence Suidas and He- the shafts of the ancient silver mines, 
 sychius in v. npoo-cfxiurj, aKap<f)ci)if, ' for which this mountainous region was 
 crv^QXTfia. so celebrated, have been discovered in
 
 634 
 
 MIXING PROCESSES 
 
 not far from the sea, on the eastern coast; and if the hole 
 which Chandler'* saw upon Mount Hymettus, was really, as he 
 conjectures, a shaft, it follows that some at least had a consider- 
 able width, for the circular opening was of more than forty feet 
 in diameter; at the bottom of the hole two narrow passages led 
 into the hill in opposite directions. It was also the practice, 
 according to Vitruvius, to make large hollows in the silver 
 mines''. The pillars, which were left standing for the support 
 of the overlying mountain, were called opfiot; and more com- 
 monly fjL6o-0KpLV6L^^\ as they at the same time served for the 
 divisions between the different compartments, or, as they were 
 called, workshops. As these pillars contained ore, the pro- 
 prietors were tempted by their cupidity to remove them, though 
 by law they were strictly prohibited from doing so: in the time 
 of the orator Lycurgus the wealthy Diphilus was condemned to 
 death for this offence'^. The opening of new mines was called 
 
 a small shrubby plain not far from the 
 sea, on the eastern coast ; and a speci- 
 men of one, lately found, was shown 
 to me at Athens." 
 
 «* Travels, chap. 30. 
 
 65" vii. 7. 
 
 ^^ Yit. X. Orat. in Plutarch, vol. vi. 
 p. 256, ed. Tubingen, Pollux iii. 87, 
 vii. 98, Lex. Seg. p. 280, Phot, in v. 
 who expressly states them to be boun- 
 daries. Tliey are called op^oi in Lex. 
 Seg. p. 205, dnoaeax^v tovs opfiovs tov 
 iierdWov : uTrocre^at to diacrelcraL kul 
 KLvrjaaL. opjxoi 8e dcriv wancp K'.oves 
 Toil /xerdXXov, ovtoi S' rjaav Koi opci Trjs 
 €Kd(rTT]s p.epi8os, rjv epiaOcoauTO rrapa 
 TT)s TToXeco?. The paragogic v of utto- 
 aeo-x^v alone shows that the gloss is 
 corrupt, and if dnoaeo-x^tv be substi- 
 tuted, this, as well as the aorist utto- 
 o-€|ai, remains unknov/n and suspici- 
 ous : but the sense is clear. It refers 
 to the cutting or working of the sup- 
 ports of the mines, by which they were 
 undermined and shaken, so as to cre- 
 ate a danger of the overlying mass 
 falling in, wldch in the Lives of the 
 Ten Orators is called tovs pca-oKpiue'is 
 
 v(/)eXerj/, and in Lex. Seg. p. 315, imop- 
 vTTiiv TO fjLeTaXkov. To the same sup- 
 ports refer two other glosses in Lex. 
 Seg. p. 286, which perhaps belong to 
 one another ; onoepKels Kioves : ol Toiv 
 fiCTdWcov KLOves, and opoi : oti KaTO. 
 p-eprj Tivd €[xia6ovvTO tu dpyvpela, opois 
 diGKeKpipeva. [In a fragment of a 
 Rhetorical Lexicon, published by Mr. 
 Dobree after his edition of Photius, 
 the following gloss occurs (p. 673) ; 
 MeaoKplvT] (/xecro/<pii/eT?) : ovtco be Xe- 
 yovTai ol iv toIs vno ytjv epyois gtvKoi, 
 o\ vTTofiacTTd^ovcn to. ^dprj tci eirdvco 
 Twv peTokXcov (Icrl 6e e^ avrrjs tt^s yrjs 
 KaraXeXei^fteVa vTrepeio-fxaTa. They 
 are also called Kioves in an Inscription 
 in Corp. Inscript. Gr. No. 162. — 
 TuANSL.3 Concerning the supports 
 used in mining by the Romans, see J. 
 C. J. Bethe, Commentatio de Hispanise 
 antiquse re metallica ad locum Stra- 
 bonis, lib. iii. Gottingen, 1808, 4to. 
 which treatise may be also consulted 
 upon the other technical subjects, for 
 which I have not referred to it. 
 ^'' Vit. Dec. Orat. ut sup.
 
 USED AT LAURION. 635 
 
 KaivoTOjjielv or Kaivorofila^^, and on account of the great risk 
 and expense^ no one would willingly undertake it. If the spe- 
 culator was successful, he was amply remunerated for his 
 undertaking; if unsuccessful, he lost all his trouble and ex- 
 pense: on which account Xenophon proposed to form com- 
 panies for this purpose, of which I shall afterwards treat. The 
 ancients speak in general terms of the unwholesome evapora- 
 tion from silver mines^% and the noxious atmosphere of those 
 in Attica is particularly mentioned^"; although the Greeks as 
 well as the Romans were acquainted with the use of shafts for 
 ventilation, which the former called -^vxaycoyia'^^ In what 
 manner the water was withdrawn from the mines, we are not 
 informed; it is however probable that the Greeks made use of 
 the same artificial means as the Romans'^ The removal of the 
 ore appears to have been performed partly by machines and 
 partly by men, as was the case in Spain and Egypt, in which 
 latter country the younger slaves brought the ore through the 
 adits to the surface of the soil: whether however the miners in 
 Attica used leather bags for this purpose, and were on that 
 account called bag-carriers {Ov\aKocj)6poi), is, to say the least, 
 uncertain; for according to the grammarians these bags con- 
 tained their food'\ The stamping of the ore at the foundries 
 in order to facilitate its separation from the useless parts of the 
 stone, was generally performed in stone mortars with iron 
 pestles. In this manner the Egyptians reduced the gold ore to 
 the size of a vetch, then ground it in hand-mills and washed it on 
 inclined planks, by pouring water over it; which is the account 
 given by a Hippocratean writer of the treatment of gold ore'*. 
 
 ^^ This expression was translated 
 from the particular sense of opening 
 fresh mines to signify anythhig new, 
 Poll. vii. 98, Phot, in v. KaivoTO}iiiv. 
 
 ^^ Casaubon ad Strab. iii. p. 101. 
 
 70 Xenoph. Socr. Mem. iii. 6, 12, 
 Plutarch. Corap. Nic. et Crass, init. 
 
 71 Lex. Seg. p. 317, and Etym. in v. 
 •vL-vyaycbyia : at 6vp'ihes tcov fxeToXkoiv 
 ai irpos to ai/a>//'i;;^eiv yLyvofMevai. 
 
 sqq. Ameilhon in the M 'moire quoted 
 below, p. 494. 
 
 73 Pollux vii. 100, X. 149, with the 
 commentators, and Hesychius in v. 
 6vXaKo(f)6pciy according to whom they 
 were also called 7rT]pocf)6poi. Both 
 6v\aKos and rrrjpa generally mean a 
 small bag, such as a travelling bag or 
 a bag for carrying bread. 
 
 '"^ Diod. xiii. 12, 13. Agatharchides 
 
 '^ Concerning these see Reitemeier de mari rubro ap. Phot. Bibhothec. p. 
 ut sup. p. 114 sqq. Bethe ut sup. p. 32 | 1342, Hippocrates de victus rat. 1, 4.
 
 636 SMELTING OPERATIONS 
 
 In Spain it was bruised in the same manner, and then, if Pliny- 
 does not invert the proper order, first washed and afterwards 
 calcined and pounded; even the quicksilver ore, from which cin- 
 nabar was prepared, was similarly treated; that is, first burnt, 
 in which operation a part of the quicksilver evaporated, and 
 then pounded with iron pestles, ground, and washed^\ In 
 Greece the labourers in the foundries made use of a sieve for 
 washing the comminuted ore, and it is mentioned among the 
 implements of the miners, by the appropriate name craKa^'^^. 
 This method of treating ore was not only in use in ancient 
 times; but it was the only one employed either during the 
 middle ages or in more recent times, until the discovery of 
 stamp-works-'. 
 
 § 5. Smelting Operations at Laurion. 
 
 Upon the art of smelting in the foundries of Laurion, nothing 
 definite is known. That the Athenians made use of the bellows 
 and of charcoal is not improbable, the latter indeed may be 
 fairly inferred (notwithstanding the doubts expressed by Reite- 
 meier) from the account of the charcoal sellers, or rather char- 
 coal burners; from which business a large portion of the 
 Acharnians in particular obtained their livelihood. 
 
 The art of smelting among the ancients was so imperfect, 
 that even in the time of Strabo, when it had received consider- 
 able improvements, there was still no profit to be gained by 
 extracting silver from lead ore in which it was present in small 
 proportions'^; and the early Athenians had, in comparison with 
 their successors (who were themselves not the most perfect 
 masters of chemistry), so slight a knowledge of the manage- 
 
 ^^ Pliu. xxxiii. 21. Quod effossum \ num. 3. Chassot de Florencourt upon 
 est^ tunditur, lavatur, uritur, molitiir in j the Klines of the Ancients (Gottingen, 
 farinam : the addition, ac pilis tundunt, 1785), p. 24 sqq. Reitemeier ut sup. p. 
 appears to refer back to tuyuUtur, but 121 sqq. 
 
 its position is such that the passage is j "^^ On this point see Beckmann ut 
 perhaps coirupt. sup. vol. iv. part iii. p. 333, Chassot 
 
 '^ Polhix vii. 97. X. 149. ■ de Florencourt, p. 37, 51, Reitemeier, 
 
 '''' Upon this subject see Beckmann, i p. 133. 
 History of Inventions, vol. v, part i. j
 
 AT LAURION. 63? 
 
 ment of ore, that, according to the same writer, not only was 
 that which had been thrown away as useless stone subsequently 
 used; but the old scoriee were again employed for the purpose 
 of extracting silver^^ According to Pliny^% the ancients could 
 not smelt any silver without some mixture of lead [plumbum 
 nigrum') or gray lead {galena, molybdcena) ; he appears, however, 
 to mean only ores in which the silver was combined with some 
 other metal to which it has a less powerful affinity than to lead. 
 At Laurion it was not necessary, at least in many places, to add 
 any lead, it being already present in the ores. Pliny states in 
 general terms the manner in which argentiferous lead ores were 
 treated^ ^; and there can be no doubt that this was the method 
 adopted in Attica. According to his account the ore was first 
 melted down to stannum, a composition of pure silver and lead: 
 then this material was brought to the refining oven, where the 
 silver was separated, and the lead appeared half glazed in the 
 form of litharge, which as well as gray lead the ancients call 
 galena and molybdeena: this last substance was afterwards 
 cooled, and the lead {plumbum nigrum, fjLoXv^So?, to distinguish 
 it from tin, plumbum album, or candidum, Kaaalrepo^) was pro- 
 duced. 
 
 Here the investigation into the technical part of this ques- 
 tion would terminate, were it not necessary to inquire what is 
 meant by the Athenian spuma argenti, by KejxP^^ ^^d Key- 
 ')(p€a)v, and, lastly, by the substance called Lauriotis, from 
 Laurion. 
 
 The spuma argenti, which was employed in medicine, was 
 chiefly a product of the silver foundries; and according to 
 some authorities there were three kinds of it ; the best called 
 chrysitis, the next arg^^itis, and the worst molybditis, which 
 appear to have differed principally in the colour, although. 
 
 73 Strabo ix. p. 275, Ka\ 8f} kcu oi I ^^ xxxiv. 47. See Beckmann lit sup. 
 epyaCofievoi t^s fj-eToXXeias dadevcos ' vol. iv. part 3, p. 332 — 335, Cliassot de 
 VTraKovovaTjs ttjv nnXaiau cKjSoXdSa Koi . Floreneourt, p. 35 sqq. Upon the 
 aKcopiav duaxoivevovrcs evpicTKov en i^ method of the ancients of striking the 
 avTTii dnoKadaipofxevov dpyvpiov, rcov metal during the process of fusion, see 
 dpxaicov dnelpfos KUfxivevovTcov. i Reitemeier, p. 79 sqq. 
 
 8» xxxiii. 31. '
 
 638 SMELTING OPERATIONS 
 
 according to Pliny, the first was made from the ore itself, the 
 second from silver {i.e. probably it was produced at the smelt- 
 ing of silver) ; and the third from lead, as at Puteoli. " There 
 is the same difference,^^ he observes^ *' between it and scorige, 
 as between foam and froth. — The former is the impure portion 
 (vitium) of the substance given off during the process of purifi- 
 cation, the latter when it is already purified." The Athenian 
 was considered the best. Dioscorides and other Greek writers 
 call it lithargyrus^^ As some writers mentioned by Pliny 
 called a species of it molybdeena, which is the term for litharge, 
 and the Italians and French still call the same substance by this 
 name {litargirio, litargio, lit urge), the common opinion is cer- 
 tainly probable that spuma argenti is the same as litharge; 
 which, as being a separation of the impure part of the ore in 
 the second stage of refinement, and having an unmetallic 
 appearance, might be called the vitium of the purified substance, 
 in opposition to the slacks which ran off during tlie smelting of 
 the ore, and were separated while the ores still contained a large 
 proportion of unmetallic substance, until the metal consisting 
 of silver and lead appeared, lliose who were less accurate in 
 their language might at the same time consider litharge as slacks, 
 and therefore lithargyrus as coming under that denomination''^ 
 Spuma argenti was however also distinguished from molybdsena 
 or htharge, for that litharge was called the best which looked 
 like lithargyrus^*; but in order not to be misled by this state- 
 ment, it must be borne in mind that by spuma argenti and 
 lithargyrus we should understand a species of litharge particu- 
 larly prepared for medicinal purposes, which differed not essen- 
 tially, but only by a contrary treatment, from the common 
 molybdsena ; and this explanation removes all difficulties. 
 
 The expressions Key^P^^ ^^^ /ceyxp^cov are more obscure. 
 The latter is a term used by a plaintiff in an oration of Demos- 
 thenes^^ for a separate foundry in the Laurian silver-mines. 
 
 ^* riin. xxxiii. 35, chiefly from ' ^^ See Salmas. Exerc. Plin. p. 
 Dioscorid. v. 102, comp. Oribasius xii. i 1079, 1082. 
 
 fol. 228 B. quoted by Hardouin, who I ^* Dioscorid. v. 100, cf. Plin. xxxiv. 
 however does not entirely agi'ee with 53. 
 the other writers. ^^ C. Pantaenet. p. 974, 15.
 
 AT LAURION. 
 
 6.39 
 
 without however any account as to its nature. The explana- 
 tions of the grammarians are so indefinite and obscure that 
 they appear to have had little knowledge of its import. Photius 
 and the compiler of the Rhetorical Lexicon^® state that Ace7- 
 XP^^J^ was a place at Athens, i.e. in Attica, where the apyvplrcs 
 Kejxpo^ and the sand from the mines were purified. It might, 
 therefore, mean the works upon which the comminuted ore 
 was washed. In this case it would have been called Keyxpos 
 or millet, from having been first bruised or washed down to the 
 size of a grain of millet, in the same manner as it is said that 
 in the Egyptian foundries the gold ore was ground down to the 
 size of a vetch : but we are compelled by other statements to 
 give up this idea. Pollux*^" observes that the slacks of iron 
 were called aKcopla (which was the general name for all slacks), 
 as the flower of gold was called dSafjuas and the impurity of 
 silver Kep^vos; which is only a difi'erent form of K6yxpo9. 
 The latter evidently cannot here mean pounded ore ; but must 
 signify a refuse given off in the smelting of the silver ore, as 
 scoria in the case of iron, and adamas in that of gold. The 
 dBd/jLa<; is, according to the clear account of Plato ^% a substance 
 unknown to us, of a black colour, and great brittleness, like 
 copper and silver intimately combined with gold, only separable 
 
 ^^ Lex. Seg. p. 271. Keyxp^oiv: 
 TOTTOS ^Adrjinjaiv ovtco KoXovfievos, onov 
 €Ka6aip€T0 fj dpyvplris Keyxpoi Kai yj/'dn- 
 [los T) dno rav dpyvpiav dva(})epop.€vr}. 
 Similarly Pliny in the first article. 
 
 ^^ vii. 90. TavTTjs 8e (-yj)? (nBrjpiTi- 
 dos) TO Kadapfia (TKinpiav wv6fj.a^ov, 
 ^cnrep tov xP'^^'^^ "^^ (ivdos dddpavra 
 Koi TOV Tcov dpyvpicov KoviopTov Kepxvov. 
 KoviopTos is dKuOapala : see Salmasius 
 Exerc. Plin. p. 1082. 
 
 88 Polit. p. 303 E, Tim. p. 59 B. In 
 Pliny xxxvii. 15, some diamonds are 
 called cenchri, where Salmasius sup- 
 poses a confusion of the true diamond 
 with this impurity given off in the 
 fusion of gold. Hardouin is of a con- 
 trary opinion, and although Pliny as 
 well as his interpreter Salmasius fre- 
 quently confound different subjects. 
 
 yet diamonds may really have been 
 called Kcyxpoi, from the small size of 
 grains of millet, in the same manner 
 that another stone in Plin. xxxvii. 13, 
 is called cenchritis. I have hoped in 
 vain to find an investigation upon the 
 adamas arising in the fusion of gold in 
 Ameilhon's Me'moire sur I'exploitation 
 des mines d'or, in the iSIem. de I'Acad. 
 des Inscriptions, vol. xlvi. p. 477 sqq. 
 although in p. 565 sqq. he treats of 
 the smelting and purification of this 
 metal. I may also mention that this 
 memoir might have been more fre- 
 quently quoted than it has by me, as 
 several points are well explained in it : 
 but most of the subjects treated there 
 are too remote from my pui-pose, or 
 are already mentioned in other well- 
 known books.
 
 640 SMELTING OPERATIONS 
 
 in the fire ; and called the flower of gold by Pollux, probably 
 from its being an efflorescence arising during the fusion of 
 this metal. 
 
 The nature of the impurity which in the fusion of silver 
 was called Keyx^po^;, cannot be determined with certainty, our 
 knowledge of the smelting processes of the ancients being very 
 imperfect; but the opinion of Salmasius^^ appears to me most 
 probable, that Key^^pof; and spuma argenti or lithargyrus are 
 identical. The different names do not render it necessary to 
 consider the substances as materially unlike, as slight varia- 
 tions determined by the different processes adopted might be 
 differently signified : in what manner, however, the litharge 
 w^as obtained which bore the name of Kejxp^'^y ^^'^ shall presently 
 see. That Pollux should call Keyxpo9 an impurity of the 
 metal, although, as being litharge, it was a substance that 
 could be applied to various uses, cannot be a matter of surprise; 
 for even the spuma argenti is called scoriae and refuse {vitium). 
 If Pollux is correct in classing the adamas with the KeyxP^^y 
 we have another reason for considering the latter to be litharge, 
 lithargyrus being called the flower of silver, as adamas the 
 flower of gold. Now^ Harpocration's obscure explanation of 
 Kejxp^^^ may be reconciled with this supposition. For 
 according to his statement, it means the purifying-place, where 
 the Kejxpo^ from the metals was cooled, as Theophrastus 
 mentioned®". 
 
 The expression receives some light by comparing what is 
 said by other writers of the flower of copper (xoXkov av6o<i, 
 flos aeris), the name of which alone seems to prove some 
 affinity or similarity of origin with lithargyrus, or the flower of 
 silver. For when the copper has been smelted, and the last 
 impurity or all the foreign parts have been separated from it. 
 
 *^ Ut sup. p. 1078 — 1082, in which, is copied by Suidas and Photius in the 
 
 however, there is much error and con- 
 fusion. 
 
 ^" Ilarpocrat. in v. Kfyxp^oiv : to 
 
 Ka3api(TTT]piOV, OTTOV TTjV €K TWV jXeTok- 
 
 Xcoi/ Kfyxpou dif-^vxov, o)? VTToarjixaivei 
 Q€6<j>pa(TTns (V t<o nepl pfraWcov. This 
 
 second article. Kuster's conjecture 
 ipyaa-Ti-jptov for KadapiaTTjpiou, and his 
 acquiescence in the explanation of 
 Photius in the first article, only prove 
 his want of reflection upon the subject.
 
 AT LAURION. 641 
 
 It is again, for the purpose of finishing the process, fused in 
 the same or another oven, and cooled in water: by this means 
 an efflorescence is formed upon the surface of the metallic cake, 
 which was called the flower of copper : Dioscorides says that it 
 resembles millet in its form {KeyxpoeiBes rS pvO/juS); Pliny 
 compares it with the scales or pods of millet {milii squamce), 
 and the Scholiast of Nicander with mustard seed^'. It is easy, 
 therefore, to see that this process is the same in reference to 
 copper as that of which Harpocration speaks in reference to 
 silver, and that the Key^pos^ which was produced in the silver 
 foundries, must also have been an efflorescence, in shape like 
 the pod of a vegetable, arising from the cake of silver. In the 
 last stage of the refining of copper, particularly of the inferior 
 kinds, something similar is formed according to the process 
 now in use. 
 
 It is probable, therefore, that this fcey^pecbv at the silver 
 foundries was in fact the foundry where the silver which had 
 been already fused was refined : the impurity detached in this 
 stage, was called Key')(^po9, and perhaps chiefly consisted of 
 glazed lead ; and here the silver was again cooled with water. 
 By this method of viewing the subject all difficulty is removed; 
 for that Harpocration should state that the Key')(^pos and not 
 the metal itself was cooled is quite natural in a grammarian of 
 considerable authority on other subjects, but ignorant of metal- 
 lurgy. Schneider^'' explains Keyxpos to be granulated metal; 
 but apparently w^ithout reason ; nor is it at all probable that 
 silver should have been fused in a granulated form. 
 
 Lastly, with respect to the Lauriotis, it will not be necessary 
 to dwell so long on it. The ancients, as is well known, not 
 only include zinc ore and calamine under the name Cadmia, 
 but also the refuse, which in the fusion of ores containing zinc 
 adheres to the sides of the fumace®% and they expressly remark 
 that the cadmia or refuse was found in silver foundries® ^ 
 
 ®' Dioscorid. v. 88, Plin. xxxiv. 24, 
 and there Hardouin and Salinasius ut 
 sup. p, 1078, Scliol. Nicand. Tlier. 257- 
 
 ^'^ Greek Dictionary in v. ^likKavQ-q. 
 
 ^3 See Beckmann, History of Inven- 
 
 tions, vol. iii. part 3, num. 3. 
 
 ^* Dioscorid. v, 84. From hini Plin, 
 xxxiv. 22, and from the latter waiter 
 again Isidorus, as quoted by Hardouin- 
 
 2 T
 
 GV2 WHETHER LAl'RTOX 
 
 They mention in connexion with this substance the flower of 
 zinc {pompholyx) as the finest and whitest sublimate, and the 
 spodos, a similar refuse, but of a harder and coarser texture, and 
 of a darker colour, which was scraped off the walls of the fur- 
 nace, mingled with ashes and sometimes with charcoal : both, 
 like the spuma argenti and the flower of copper, were used 
 in medicine®\ The spodos of the silver foundries was called 
 Lauriotis®^; a proof that ores of zinc were present in the 
 mines of Laurion. This spodos of Attica was probably much 
 esteemed, since the refuse of silver foundries (as the ancients 
 remark) was whiter and finer than that which came from the 
 copper foundries. 
 
 § 6. Whether haurion coined Money, 
 
 It might be supposed that Laurion was also the mint of 
 Attica, as the Athenian silver coins are called in joke Laurian 
 owls^'^; but they received this appellation from the place 
 where the silver was found, and not from the money being 
 coined there ^ and it is proved incontestably by an ancient 
 inscription that the mint for striking the silver coins {apyvpo- 
 Koirelov) was in Athens*. 
 
 If subordinate corporations in Attica enjoyed the privilege 
 of stamping money, there might be ground for supposing that 
 mints existed in difi'erent Athenian towns : and in fact the 
 writers upon coins mention several supposed to have been 
 struck by townis or bodies in Attica, \dz., Anaphlystus, the 
 Azetini, Decelea, Eleusis, Eradse, Laurion, Marathon, and 
 Salamis^^. There appears, however, to be no reason for sup- 
 posing that any one of them exercised the right of coining 
 
 ^^ Dioseorid. v. 85. Tlin, xxxiv. 33. j ^7 Aristoph. Av. HOC. Schol. Aris- 
 Comp. Galen and Oribasius in the toph. Eq. 1091. Hesy chins, Suidas, 
 passages quoted by Hardouin. and other collectors of glosses and 
 
 ^^ Plin. xxxiv. 34. At the conclu- proverbs, 
 sion of these technical inquiries I * See above note A, page 144.— 
 should state that I have been assisted Traxsl. 
 in them by the judgment of two I »8 g^^ Eckhel D. N. vol. ii. p. 225 
 
 scientific friends. 
 
 sqq.
 
 COINED MONEY. 643 
 
 before the time of the Romans, particularly as a simple investi- 
 gation sufficiently proves that most of the coins referred to 
 these places are not of Athenian origin. 
 
 Who has ever heard of Eradee or of the Azetini in Attica? 
 which undoubtedly are diflferent from the demi Azenia and 
 Eroiadse. In order to coin money it was necessary that there 
 should be a corporation : how then could Laurion, which was a 
 mining district, and not a demus, have stamped coins with its 
 name? The supposed inscription AATPEI2N upon two coins 
 in the museum of Theupoli must be changed with Sestini into 
 MTPEflN, and referred to Myra in Lysia, particularly as 
 AATPEflN is not a form derivable from Laurion, which would 
 be AATPIEflN or AATPinTflN, and not, as Eckhel sup- 
 poses, AATPIflN. The coins attributed to Anaphlystus be- 
 long to Anactorium, with the exception of a copper coin invented 
 by Goltz. The coins marked with the word XAAAMINION 
 should be referred to the island of Cyprus, where Pellerin 
 obtained them : and others with the letters XA prove nothing 
 whatever for the Athenian demus. With regard to Marathon, 
 Hardouin alone mentions one coin belonging to it, with the 
 unabbreviated inscription MAPA0I2N AHMOX, a circum- 
 stance which makes his statement suspicious. He does not 
 mention the place where it was preserved, and nobody has since 
 seen a similar coin; so that, if the whole is not a mere inven- 
 tion, he had perhaps read upon some coin the initial letters of 
 these words, the explanation of which he gives as a fact. It 
 seems utterly inexplicable how the island of Helena or Crana^, 
 upon which, as far as is known, there was not even a village, 
 should have struck coins. There can be no doubt therefore 
 that the silver coins of Helena are an invention of Goltz; and 
 there is no occasion why other coins of the emperors, with the 
 inscription of the Cranaans, should be referred to the island of 
 Attica: the coin quoted by Hardouin with the wonderfully 
 explicit inscription of EAENITflN TflN KAI KPANAA- 
 TflN could hardly have had a real existence : but a copper coin 
 with the words KPANAIflN AOH cannot well be referred to 
 any other place than the Attic Cranae; it must however belong 
 to the times of the emperors, when Cranae may perhaps have 
 
 2t 2
 
 644 WHETIIPTR LAURTON COINED MONEY. 
 
 been a demus; probably after the tribe of Hadrian had been 
 instituted, additional demi were created in order to fill it. 
 Besides these, there are genuine brass coins of Eleusis and 
 Decelea, which no doubt also belong to the time of the Roman 
 dominion? and after the great fall which Athens sustained 
 under the Romans, it is easy to conceive that the demi were 
 allowed to stamp small copper coins. The coins attributed to 
 Prasia, the demus of Attica, have been already set aside by 
 Eckhel. 
 
 § 7* Mode of granting the Mines, 
 
 It now remains for us to investigate the following important 
 questions, viz. In whom was the right of property in the mines 
 of Laurion vested ? By whom and on whose account were they 
 worked ? What advantage did their produce afibrd to the state 
 and to individuals ? And what were the duties, rights, and 
 immunities of the mine proprietors? With regard to all these 
 points nothing will be found in modern writers but confused 
 statements, or assertions unsupported by any satisfactory proof. 
 The account which I propose to give will be derived from dis- 
 tinct authorities, and founded on a close investigation of the 
 subject. 
 
 As long as Attica remained free, no direct tax was imposed 
 either upon the produce or value of landed property, except 
 that during the continuance of peace the liturgies, which were 
 necessary for the service of the state and of religion, fell upon 
 property generally, and necessarily for the most part upon 
 visible (ova la (fiavepa) or landed property, w^hich in case of 
 preparations for war was also liable to the trierarchy and the 
 payment of extraordinary taxes {elo-cfiopal). The circumstances 
 however which determined this liability were directly reversed 
 in the case of mines: the proprietor of these paid an annual 
 tax into the public treasury; to the liturgies and extraordinary 
 property taxes from a possession of this kind he contributed 
 nothing. From this fact, which I shall presently put out of 
 doubt, it is fair to infer, agreeably moreover to all accounts on 
 the subject, that mines were not like other lands the freehold
 
 MODE OF GRANTING THE MINES. 
 
 645 
 
 property of the citizens, but in the absolute dominion of the 
 state; and that they were transferred by it to individuals, under 
 certain legal conditions, to make what use of them they should 
 think proper. 
 
 The Romans for a considerable period let the mines be- 
 longing to the state for a term of years, until it was found more 
 profitable to work them at the public cost*^ Now that this is 
 the most disadvantageous mode of letting has been proved by 
 the experience both of ancient and modern times; for the 
 tenant works them wastefully and unfairly; he rifles the rich 
 ores, leaving the less productive unworked; and while he endea- 
 vours by a large number of labourers to exhaust the mines 
 during the period of his lease, he pays no attention to the pil- 
 laring and chambering, without which the value of the mines is 
 much diminished. Nor is it easy to enforce from the tenant a 
 strict compliance with the conditions of the lease; and at the 
 expiration of his term the mines are let at a lower rent, having 
 in the interim lost a considerable portion of their value. 
 
 The state of Athens, whether from policy or accident, had 
 avoided this injurious practice: it granted to private individuals 
 the mines in the Athenian territory on perpetual leases, which 
 might be transferred to a third person by inheritance or sale'°% 
 and in short by every kind of legal conveyance. The possession 
 was therefore obtained by the payment of a sum of money once 
 for all, as purchase or entrance money. Thus Demosthenes 
 mentions the buying of mines from the state as the ordinary 
 proceeding, and Panteenetus purchased a mine from the people 
 for 90 minas'"*'. This sum cannot have been an annual rent, 
 for as its amount depended upon the produce of the mine, it 
 could not have been definitely stated beforehand. 
 
 ^» Reitemeier ut sup. p. 99 sqq. 
 
 lo" ^sch. c. Timai-ch. p. 121, De- 
 mosth. c. Pantsenet. passim. 
 
 i"i Demosth. ut sup. p. 973, 13, 
 o(TTis av fxeraXXov napa rrjs TrdXeeoy 
 7rpir]Tai. And before in the same 
 speech : KUTa^oXrjv rrj noKei tov fieraX- 
 \ov, 6 eyo) eirpidp.T]u evvevrjKovra p-vav. 
 The oration called rrpos MtjkvBov pe- 
 
 raXkiKos, falsely ascribed to Dmarchus, 
 began with the words Trpidpevoi peraX- 
 Xov (o aVSpef. See Dionys. Dinarch. 
 p. 119, 11, ed. Sylb. Dionysius after- 
 wards calls this pia6a>(Taa-6ah in his 
 own language ; which, however, as the 
 sale was only a perpetual lease, is the 
 natural word, and frequently occurs in 
 the grammarians.
 
 646 MODE OF GRANTING THE MINES. 
 
 There remains now only one objection that can be urged; 
 viz. that it was allowed to open new works without the payment 
 of any purchase money; and that the money paid by Pantie- 
 netus might have been for a mine already opened, which the 
 state had obtained by confiscation, an occurrence by no means 
 uncommon; and to confirm this supposition the argument 
 of the speech against Panteenetus'"^ might be cited, in which 
 it is stated that the purchase money was paid in silver 
 from the mine, which implies that the mine was already pro- 
 ducing metal. But if this grammarian were worthy of credit as 
 to a fact about which he could not have possessed any better 
 knowledge than ourselves, it does not by any means follow that 
 a confiscated mine is intended; for it could scarcely have been 
 compulsory upon a tenant to pay to the state the purchase 
 money of a new mine, if, after having expended his trouble and 
 capital, he was unsuccessful in finding any ore. It is far more 
 probable that any person was allowed to dig for ore in those 
 parts of the mountain which had not yet been alienated, and 
 that he was not compelled to purchase the soil until he 
 found productive ores, and w^as willing to work them. As 
 the contradictory of this supposition would be absurd, it is 
 manifest that the purchase money even of a newly opened mine 
 might have been paid with silver from the mine itself. Pantse- 
 netus however was possessed of other mines besides this one; 
 and it is moreover unnecessary to assume that this silver came 
 directly from the mines. 
 
 Lastly, it is stated by Harpocration (who generally follows 
 the authority of Aristotle) that the poletse had the duty of 
 superintending all sales of public property, particularly those of 
 customs and other duties, of mines, leases, and confiscated pro- 
 perty"'^. In this passage the sale of the mines is clearly 
 distinguished from that of leases and of private property 
 accruing to the state, and the mines which were sold must 
 necessarily have been newly opened. 
 
 '"^ P. 964, 13. I iJna3a>(r€is kol to. drj^ievofieva. This is 
 
 103 iiarpocrat. in v. 7ra)X?;r«i. 8loi- transcribed by Siiidas, Photius, and 
 
 Kova-i be TO. nnrpaa-Koixeva vno r^v Lex. Seg. p. 21)1. 
 
 TTuXeoiS TTOiVTa, tcXt) k(u fieraXXa kcii
 
 MODE OF GRANTING THE MINES. 647 
 
 In this conveyance of public property to a perpetual tenant, 
 the boundaries of the allotment purchased were accurately 
 defined/ and a documentary instrument {Btaypacj)?]) was taken '*'\ 
 For this purpose some knowledge of mine surveying was requi- 
 site, which, from the want of the necessary instruments, must 
 have been very imperfect^ "^ 
 
 In addition to the purchase money, the purchaser paid the 
 twenty-fourth part of the produce of the new mine; that is, of 
 the gross, and not the nett produce, as the amount of the latter 
 would have been too inconsiderable' "^ By these means all the 
 disadvantages were avoided which might arise from letting the 
 mines for a term of years. If a tenant exhausted the ore in a 
 short time, the duty upon the metal obtained was augmented; 
 and if he worked the rich ores alone, he injured himself. If 
 the proprietor violated the laws and conditions under which 
 the mine was made over to him, for example, if the annual duty 
 was not paid, the state could resume the mine; if however he 
 did not act contrary to the agreement, this species of property 
 was equally secure with other landed estates. In short the 
 circumstances of the tenure were the same as those, which, 
 
 *°^ Harpocrat. Suid. and Zonaras in 
 V. btaypa(prj. 7] SiarvTrcDcris rcov Trnrpacr- 
 KOfievcov /xerdXXcoJ' Sr/Xoucra bia ypofx- 
 yLUToav GTTu noias (ipx^l^ H-^XP'- '^'^^^^ 
 TTiTrpdaKeTaL Treparos. Upon the boun- 
 daries comp. Demosth. ut sup. p. 977? 
 
 chase money and yearly duty were 
 connected is stated by Barthelemy, 
 Anachars. vol. v. cl'.ap. 59. Suidas 
 omits the purchase money, according 
 to the usual habit of the grammarians 
 of stating the subject imperfectly ; what 
 
 and above note 6G. [See Corp. In- i he says of newly opened works is con- 
 script. Gr. No. 1G2. — Traxsi..] I uectcd with the fact which he wishes 
 ^'"^ See Reitemeier, p. 112 sqq. i to explain, and it is self-evident that 
 '"^ Suidas and Zonaras in v. dypd- the other px-opiietors paid the rent of 
 (f)ov p.€TaXXov diKT) ol TO. dpyvpela fie- ! the twenty-fourth part. It cannot be 
 raXXa epya^op-^voL ottov ftovKoLvro Kai- ; shov.n that there ever existed any 
 vov epyov ap^ua6ai (Zonaras more cor- j mine vvhicii was originally freehold 
 ractly a^aa-Bai) (puvepov inoiovvTo rols \ property, and not transferred by the 
 eV eKeivoLs Terayixeuois vtto tov Stjixov ' state, and subject to the payment of no 
 (i. e. tlie poleta?) Ka\ dneypafPovTo tov [ tax. It may be observed, that the tax 
 reXci!/ evcKa r(o brjpo) elKoarrjv rerdp- from the smelthig furnaces (otto Kafii- 
 Trjv TOV Koivov pieTuWov. Cf. Harpocr. vcov) of which Xenophon spealcs (de 
 and Suid. in v. dirovopLTj, whose words I Vectig. 4, 49) is the rent of the twenty- 
 will presently quote. That the pur- fourth.
 
 64S 
 
 MODE OF GRANTING THE MINES, 
 
 according to the Roman law, regulated the possession of the 
 Vectigalia in the Municipia^''^ 
 
 We are justified in assuming that all the mines of Laurion 
 were obtained in the manner just stated; of a distinction 
 between those which were held on this tenure and others which 
 were freehold property, I have been able to find no trace. All 
 the large proprietors of mines who are mentioned in ancient 
 authors, such as Nicias, Callias the brother-in-law of Cimon, 
 and the other Callias who discovered the method of preparing 
 cinnabar, together with Diphilus, Timarchus, and before him 
 his father Pantsenetus, &c. had only perpetual leases ; the state- 
 ment therefore that the mines before the time of Themistocles 
 were the absolute property of families, rests only upon the mis- 
 apprehension of Meursius'^^ The state was at all times the 
 exclusive and original owner; nor did it ever use this property 
 in any other manner than by leasing it in perpetuity. There 
 nowhere exists any proof that mines were ever let by the state 
 for a term of years; nor could there have been any stronger 
 motive for working them at the public cost than for the collec- 
 tion of the customs and other taxes: nothing indeed but a gross 
 ignorance of the public policy of Athens could have allowed 
 such a notion to be entertained^ °^; and the only fact brought in 
 support of the assertion is, that a revenue was derived by the 
 community from these mines in the age of Themistocles, as if 
 this did not arise from the purchase money and the yearly 
 rents: even Xenophon did not go so far as to recommend that 
 the mines should be worked at the public cost; he is satisfied 
 with proposing''" that the community might, in imitation of 
 private individuals, procure public slaves, and let them to mine 
 proprietors, in connexion probably with such mines as were not 
 
 '"^ See Niebuhr, Rom. Hist. vol. ii. 
 p. 376 sqq. 
 
 '"^ F. A. cap. 7j from Yitruvius vii. 
 7, where familice means slaves, nor is 
 the time before Themistocles distinctly 
 alluded to (see note 138). Meursius 
 has been followed by several writers, 
 among others by Chandler, Travels, 
 
 chap. 30. 
 
 ^"^ As Reitemeier iit sup. p. 70, and 
 Manso, Sparta, vol. iii. p. 495, suppose, 
 Meiners, vom Luxus der Athener, p. 
 57, correctly remarks that the state of 
 Athens never carried on mining at its 
 own cost. 
 
 "" De Vectig. 4.
 
 MODE OF GRANTING THE MINES. 649 
 
 as yet alienated; the object being to derive a revenue from the 
 letting of slaves in addition to the rents paid in silver: it can 
 indeed be asserted with safety that this object was never con- 
 templated. 
 
 In short the state did not in any manner interfere with 
 mining, except that it enforced its own rights and laws; to these 
 points alone its superintendence applied. The poletse sold the 
 mines, subject to the payment of the yearly rents. In the 
 observance of the laws all the members of the community had 
 an interest, and were empowered to institute public suits, in the 
 event of their violation. The account given by a modern 
 writer of "a director of the mines ^^ appointed by the public, is, 
 as far as I am aware, wholly devoid of foundation. 
 
 It is probable that the gold mines in Thrace, opposite to 
 Thasos, from the time that Athens obtained possession of them, 
 were under similar regulations. Whether the former proprietors 
 retained their property in them, or whether new possessors 
 were introduced by the Athenians either by a free grant or by 
 sale, after the manner of the cleruchiae, it is certain that the 
 proprietors paid a rent in metal, which practice had probably 
 existed under the former independent government: all new 
 mines were purchased from the people of Athens. But the 
 gold mines in Thasos and the mines of other subject countries 
 were undoubtedly retained by the tributary state ; while Athens 
 exacted from them, under the form of tribute, whatever sum it 
 pleased, without interfering with the original right of possession. 
 This however is not the object of our present inquiries*. 
 
 § 8. Amount of the Proceeds of the Mines accruing to the State^ 
 and the manner in which they were disposed of 
 
 The purchase money of mines aUenated by the state was paid 
 by the buyer directly into the pubhc treasury'^'; but with the 
 annual rent there is some doubt whether this was the case. All 
 the regular duties (even those of which the collection was easy 
 and attended with little expense, and the amount of which 
 
 * See above, b. iii. ch. 3.— Transl. ^" Demosth. c. Puutaeuet. p. 973.
 
 650 PROCEEDS OF THE MINES, 
 
 could be judged with tolerable accuracy, as, for example, the 
 protection money and the rents of the public lands) were sold 
 to individuals or companies as farmers-general: are we then to 
 suppose that an exception was made in the case of the twenty- 
 fourth of the silver, the amount of which must necessarily have 
 been very different in different years, and where, without an 
 accurate inspection of the quantity raised, the tenant was able 
 to commit great frauds ? It seems therefore probable to me 
 that this duty was sold to a farmer-general by the poletse; but, 
 although there is little objection to this hypothesis, no distinct 
 authority can be found in favour of it. 
 
 It is mentioned in Demosthenes that Eubulus, the well- 
 known manager of the Theorica, had been accused by Mcerocles 
 of unjustly exacting 20 drachmas from "those persons who 
 had purchased the mines' ^^^^ Now there can be no question 
 that the chief farmers of the rents are not here meant by " the 
 purchasers of the mines,'' We must, therefore, refer these 
 words to those who had obtained possession of the mines 
 themselves, and from the use of the definite article ''the mines'' 
 it must be supposed that Demosthenes is speaking of some 
 well-known sale of a considerable number of mines, which had 
 taken place a short time before : for it would have been a very 
 aflfected phrase, and liable to misconception, to denote all the 
 mine proprietors both old and new, by the circumlocution, 
 '' those who had purchased the mines,'^ particularly as they are 
 usually called the workers of the mines {ol epya^ofievoc iv rols 
 e/)7ot9, or iv rols fjuerdWoLs): consequently Mcerocles must be 
 considered as having been employed to collect purchase monies, 
 in which capacity he obtained, under some false pretence, 20 
 drachmas from each purchaser. 
 
 When the sausage seller in the Knights of Aristophanes^'' 
 threatens Cleon that he will buy mines, in order, as the 
 Scholiast observes, to obtain favour w^th the people by enrich- 
 ing the state, he must mean the actual possession of the mines 
 themselves, this being the only transaction by which the state 
 
 "■^ Tlapa Toiv TCI fieraWa etovTjfxevcov. I "' Ecj. 3<»1, dXKa a^f^i^as fdrjSo' 
 Demosth. de fals. leg. p. 435, 5. | ku)s wvijno^iai fieToKXa.
 
 AND MANNER OF DISPOSAL. 
 
 651 
 
 would have profited from the intervention of any particular 
 individual ; for it would be manifestly indifferent to whom the 
 duties were let ; and moreover if the letting of the duty were 
 signified, some more precise expression must necessarily have 
 been employed. 
 
 Lastly, it is stated by Ulpian that Meidias had rented the 
 silver mines from the state'**; although the vagueness of the 
 expression would lead one to imagine that he means the chief 
 farmer of the rents, we are compelled to relinquish this notion 
 upon perceiving that the commentator wishes to explain why 
 Meidias imported wood to the mines, for which a chief farmer 
 of the rents could have had no inducement. Was Meidias 
 then a tenant, or proprietor of mines ? The use of the 
 article proves nothing against this supposition in a writer of 
 such mean authority. Yet why need a moment's attention be 
 paid to the statements of this Pseudo-Ulpian ? Is there any 
 Scholiast that rivals the ignorance and confusion displayed in 
 this chaos of notes ? Because Meidias imported timber to the 
 mines, perhaps only to sell it there, or during the time that he 
 was bound to serve the state with his trireme, to indemnify 
 himself for the expenses of the trierarchy by employing his 
 ship in some profitable manner, Ulpian immediately infers, 
 from the words of Demosthenes, that Meidias rented mines. 
 This method of commenting frequently occurs in this writer, 
 and has not always been sufficiently attended to. 
 
 In the Athenian revenue the income accruing from the 
 mines was a regular receipt' '^; it arose from the purchase 
 monies and the reserved rent which was paid in silver, and 
 was exclusive of what was received from the market and the 
 public buildings"®; and consequently its amount depended upon 
 
 ''* Mefi'icrdcoTO yap to. fieraWa napa 
 TTjS TToXeo)?, a rjv Tov dpyvpLOv,p. 685 C, 
 ed. Wolf. Mi'o-^coo-t? for the granting 
 a lease of the mines cannot appear an 
 unnatural expression, as the Greek 
 language had no separate term for this 
 idea. See Photius in v. ix€(TOKpLve7s, 
 Harpocr. and Said, in v. dnovoixfj, and 
 above notes 6fi and 101. All those 
 
 instances, however, in which ^.taOoi- 
 aaaOaL is used of the mines, occur in 
 later writers, viz., the grammarians 
 and Dionysius. The words for it in 
 the ancient authors are ayveiadai and 
 TrplacrBaL. 
 
 ^'* Cf. Aristoph. Vesp. (io? sqq. 
 
 "« Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 49.
 
 632 PROCEEDS OF THE MINES, 
 
 the greater or less number of mines sold by the state, upon the 
 quaUty of the ores, and the greater or less activity with which 
 the working was carried on : by which circumstances the tenant 
 would naturally be guided in the amount of his offer. In the 
 time of Socrates (as has been before remarked) the receipts 
 from this source had already begun to decrease ; we have also 
 statements of their amount in the age of Themistocles, but 
 obscurely and inaccurately expressed. 
 
 The money accruing from the mines was originally distri- 
 buted among all the citizens in the same manner as the 
 Theoricon in later times. Every person whose name was 
 registered in the book of the Lexiarchs was entitled to receive 
 his portion ^^^ When, however, at the recommendation of 
 Themistocles, the Athenians, instead of thus wasting the public 
 revenue, resolved to apply this money to ship building, in the 
 w^ar against the ^ginetans, each person was (as Herodotus 
 states) to have received 10 drachmas for his share' '^ If we 
 reckon with this historian that there were 30,000 citizens in 
 Athens, the whole sum must have amounted to 50 talents ; but 
 it wiU be better to assume 20,000 as the average number of the 
 adult Athenians; and accordingly there were about 33^ talents 
 for the distribution. And that the distribution was made 
 annually might have been presumed from the principles of the 
 Athenian administration, without the testimony of Cornelius 
 Nepos"^ We are not, therefore, to suppose that the savings 
 of several years are meant, nor merely a surplus ; but that all 
 the public money arising from the mines, as it was not required 
 for any other object, was divided among the members of the 
 community '"\ Supposing now that among these revenues no 
 purchase money of mines in actual possession is included, and 
 that the revenues of a whole year are meant, the total of the 
 produce would have annually amounted to more than 800 
 
 ^'^ Demosth. c. Leochar. p. 1091. j of absurd fancies has been broached. 
 ^'^ vii. 144. Cf. Herald. Animadv. in Salmas. Ob- 
 
 "® Themistocl. 2. serv. ad I. A. et R. vi. 3, 9. Other 
 
 **" I make this remark on account I passages of later writers which refer 
 of a passage of Aristides in the second to this point of history I pass over, as 
 lUaton. Oration, on which a sufficiency they contain nothing new.
 
 AND MANNER OF DISPOSAL. 
 
 ess 
 
 talents. I say more than 800, as the profit of the chief farmef 
 is not allowed for in the calculation ; but according to Poly- 
 senus'*', whose account is more explicit, the Athenians wished 
 to divide, as usual, 100 talents arising from the mines ; when 
 Themistocles undertook to wean them from this custom, and 
 persuaded them to give a talent apiece to the 100 most wealthy 
 citizens, to be employed by each in the equipment of a vessel ; 
 if the vessel was approved of, the talent was not reclaimed^ and 
 in the contrary case it was restored to the state, and that thus 
 the Athenians obtained 100 well-built and fast-sailing vessels. 
 Now is this account to be wholly rejected as the mere embel- 
 lishment of later writers ? It might indeed appear preferable to 
 discredit it_, when we consider that if the state received a revenue 
 of 100 talents from the mines (exclusively of the occasional receipt 
 of purchase monies), it would imply an annual produce of 2400 
 talents, a sum which is incredible; though it is certain that 
 many mines in ancient times, for instance, those of Spain and 
 Thasos, produced a very large amount of metal. But in that 
 case could Herodotus have assumed that the Athenians built 
 200 ships with SB or 50 talents ? or, taking the lowest state- 
 ment, would this sum have been sufficient for building even 
 100 triremes ? And what was done in the following years with 
 the monies received from the mines, as it is not mentioned that 
 they were afterwards distributed'^*? Herodotus probably 
 thought that the 200 ships were built from the revenues not of 
 one year, but of a term of years. We must also suppose that 
 the 100 talents mentioned by Polysenus were the revenues of 
 several years, which after the adoption of the practice suggested 
 by Themistocles, were no longer distributed, and were laid by 
 that they might be from time to time assigned to each of 
 100 trierarchs. 
 
 This mode of viewing the subject reconciles both narrations, 
 and is moreover, when considered by itself, the most probable ; 
 it also shows that the accounts of some writers who mention 
 
 '^' Strateg. i. 30, 5. 
 ^^^ Themistocl. 4. Nepos is least of 
 all to be listened to, as he speaks of a 
 
 war with Corcyra instead of that with 
 iEgina.
 
 654 
 
 PERSONS ENTITLED TO ACQUIRE MINES, 
 
 100, and of Herodotus who states that 200 ships were built 
 with the revenues from the mines, may be both true, if Themis- 
 tocles' principle had been followed for a considerable period ; 
 for if a longer series of years were taken, twice the number of 
 ships would have been built that is stated by those who referred 
 only to half the number of years. Diodorus'", in Olymp. 75, 4 
 (B.C. 477)5 speaks of a law of Themistocles, which enacted that 
 20 new triremes should be built annually; this, however, is 
 probably the same fact; and the account, which in other 
 respects may be correct, has been transferred by this careless 
 writer to later times. 
 
 § 9. Persons entitled to acquire Mines. Value of Single Shares, 
 
 Although the mines were not freehold property, the tenure 
 on which they were held was sufficiently secure. It is there- 
 fore probable that the leases of the mines could only be trans- 
 ferred to such as were entitled to the possession of landed 
 property, and consequently only to citizens, isoteles, and 
 proxeni; for the isoteles had a right to the possession of 
 land^"**, since, with the exception of political rights, they were 
 upon the same footing as the citizens ; whereas the foreigners 
 in the more limited sense [^evoi) and the resident aliens 
 {fierotKOi), neither in Athens nor in any other part of Greece, 
 were entitled to hold landed property. Xenophon proposes 
 that the state should grant to individual resident aliens, who 
 might appear worthy of it, the right of building houses and 
 holding them as property '^^; from which it is evident that by 
 law they were excluded from this privilege ; and indeed the 
 right of owning land was generally granted together with the 
 rights of citizenship, of isopolitia and proxenia, by a decree of 
 the people^*^ Hence no resident alien could with safety lend 
 money upon landed property, as he was disqualified from taking 
 
 12^ xi. 43. 
 
 '^ Lysias c. Eratosth. p. 39o, ac- 
 cording to whom Lysias and Polemar- 
 chiis, both isoteles, possessed three 
 
 houses. 
 
 '" De Vectig. 2, ad fin. 
 
 '^^ See tlie inscriptions cited in b, i. 
 note 665.
 
 PERSONS ENTITLED TO ACQI IRE MINES. 655 
 
 possession of it without he became a citizen'" % unless indeed it 
 happened that the community gave a special permission : thus 
 for example, the government of Byzantium, to reUeve itself 
 from one of its many pecuniary difficulties, gave the resident 
 ahens the privilege of holding the lands mortgaged to them, on 
 condition that they payed into the public treasury the third 
 part of the money claimed '^^. 
 
 Now that isoteles as well as citizens were possessed of 
 mines, we know from Xenophon'^^: the requisite privilege of 
 isotelia must thus have been granted by the public to such of 
 the foreigners or resident ahens as rented mines from the state, 
 for the furtherance indeed of its own interest, as it was highly 
 beneficial to the revenue that many mines should be purchased 
 and worked, and consequently that the access to them should 
 be facilitated as much as possible; but without being an 
 isoteles, no resident alien or foreigner could hold a lease of a 
 mine, though he might rent the duties for a term of years ^^". 
 
 With respect to the number of mine proprietors, there is 
 reason to believe that it was not inconsiderable ; in the speech 
 against Phaenippus they are mentioned together with the 
 husbandmen as a separate class of producers. Sometimes 
 individuals had one or a few mining shares, as, for instance, 
 Timarchus and Pantsenetus and others ; sometimes several, as 
 Nicias, Diphilus, and Callias the brother-in-law of Cimon, 
 whose wealth was chiefly derived from the mines. 
 
 The values of single shares or work-shops {ipyaarrjpia) 
 were different. Pantsenetus purchased one from the state for 
 90minas^^^; the same person had borrowed 105 minas upon 
 another share, together with 30 slaves, that is, 45 minas upon 
 the slaves of Nicobulus, and a talent upon the mine of Euergus, 
 
 ^*7 Demosth. pro Phonn. p. 946, 4, ' ra ^ovXofieva epyd^faBai eurols fierdX- 
 
 \ois. ^'Epya^eadai ev toIs fieraWois is 
 the common expression for the mine 
 proprietoi-s. I do not quote the pas- 
 sage 4, 22, as only tenants for a term 
 of years may be there meant. 
 
 '30 Plutarch. Alcib. 5. 
 
 i"" Demosth. c Pantsen. p. 973, 5. 
 
 6pa>p OTi fiT)7r<o rrjs TroXireias avr^ nap 
 vfxiv ovcTTjs ovx oios re eaoiro elaTTpaT" 
 TCLV oaa Uaaicov in\ yrj koX (TWOiKiais 
 bedavfiKOiS rjv. 
 
 '28 Pseud- Aristot. (Econ. lib. ii. 
 
 '^^ De Vectig. 4, 12, Trapex^'- yovv 
 (J] noXts) cVi ifforeXfia Koi tSuv ^evatv
 
 656 VALUE OF SINGLE SHARES. 
 
 for which sum it was bought from another private individual' "**. 
 It is soon after stated that this was not so, and soon after that 
 it was, and presently that the mine was sold together with the 
 slaves for 206 minas'". The customary price appears indeed 
 to have been a talent ; thus the mine proprietor, for whom the 
 speech against Phaenippus was written, when the mine in which 
 he had a share reverted to the state, paid 3 talents, one for 
 each share, when he wished to regain possession of the confis- 
 cated property '^\ Nor is this the only instance of several 
 partners in one mine'"; generally, however, a mining company 
 appears to have been formed by several persons who combined 
 for the purpose of opening a new work; and afterwards, if 
 fortunate enough to meet with ore, they divided the space into 
 different compartments, which were then worked independently, 
 each person possessing a separate share. Thus these partners 
 only bore the expense and loss in common, until they found a 
 sufficiently rich vein of metal. No arrangement of this kind 
 can indeed have been in use before the publication of Xeno- 
 phon's Essay upon the Revenue '^% for in that tract he recom- 
 mends that companies should be formed for working new 
 mines, and that the profit or loss should be shared equally by 
 the adventurers ; and this judicious proposal] appears to have 
 been acted upon. An association of several persons was how- 
 ever sometimes formed for working a single work-shop '^^ 
 
 '^^ Ibid. p. 976. Nicobulus had j means the state's share iu the proceeds 
 lent money upon the slaves, Euergus I of the mines, or the portion which 
 
 upon the mine, p. 976, 18; p. 972, 21. 
 
 '3-« Ibid. p. 981, 8, and p. 970, 3; 
 p. 975,21; p. 981,8. 
 
 *3^ P. 1039, 20, Kui TO TcXevToiov 
 vZv e/xe Set t^ nokei rpia rakavra Kara- 
 6e7vai, ToXaifTou Kara rnv ftepi'Sa* /xere- 
 (Txov ycipi cos fiTjUOT a>cf)e\ou, Kayco tov 
 'drjfxevOevTOS peraXXov. 
 
 '•*^ Cf. Demosth. c. Pantaenet. p. 
 977,21 ; 969, 11. 
 ■ '36 4, 32. 
 
 ^^'^ As may be infen-ed from Dem. 
 c. Pantaen. p. 969, 1 1, when the gram- 
 marians wish to explain the word 
 
 each of several sharers in the profit 
 received. If the latter explanation 
 were connect, we must understand a 
 working in common of the same mine. 
 Harpocration, and Suidas who trans- 
 cribes him, in v. aTrovofXT] : rj dnofioipaf 
 coy pepos Ti TOiV TTfpiyLyvopevcov e/c tcov 
 peToXkoiP Xap^avoiKTTjs r^s TrdXecoy rj 
 a)s diaipovpevoov eiy nXelovs piaOcorovs 
 (read p,ia6coTas, tenants) 1v eKaaros 
 Xaftu TL p.€pos. Afivapxos iv ra irpbs 
 Tovs AvKovpyov naldas noXXaKu . [ The 
 reading p-ia-diaras has been received 
 by Bekker into the text of his edition 
 
 dnovofiT), they are in doubt whether it | from two MSS. — Traxsl.]
 
 LABOUR OF SLAVES IN THE MINES. 657 
 
 Upon the boundaries of the mines purchased from the state, 
 the proprietors were required to leave supports, as has been 
 already stated. 
 
 § 10. Labour of Slaves in the Mines, 
 
 In mining, as in everything where labour was necessary, the 
 actual work was performed by slaves^ ^*. It cannot be proved 
 that in Greece free citizens ever laboured in mines or foundries 
 under the compulsion of tyrants, as has been asserted '^^ The 
 Romans condemned the oflfenders who had been enslaved by 
 public ordinance, to work in the mines, in the same manner 
 that criminals of this description are now sent to the mines of 
 Siberia: this method of punishment, however, cannot ha\'e 
 existed at Athens, as the community did not carry on any 
 mining at the public expense ; nor did it let mines for a term 
 of years together with the labourers, which was only done by 
 private individuals. The master, however, could probably 
 punish his slaves by forcing them to labour in the mines, as 
 well as in the mills ; and in general none but inferior slaves 
 were employed in them, such as barbarians and criminals. 
 Their condition was not indeed so miserable as that of the 
 slaves in the Egyptian mines, where the condemned labourers 
 worked without intermission until they were so exhausted as to 
 fall lifeless; but notwithstanding that in Attica the spirit of 
 freedom had a mild and beneficial influence even upon the 
 treatment of slaves, yet myriads of these wretched mortals are 
 said to have languished in chains in the unwholesome atmo- 
 sphere of the mines^^^ 
 
 For this degraded state of their fellow creatures the Athe- 
 nians felt no greater compassion than the other nations of 
 antiquity. In vain we seek in the social relations of the Greeks 
 
 '^8 These are the familicB in Vitruv. is said to have been possessed of an 
 
 vii. 7, where see Schneider. 
 
 1^9 The instance, which Reiteraeier 
 (p. 73) adduces is not Grecian, but re- 
 fers to a Persian satrap named Pythius 
 or Pytlies of Celaense in Phrygia, who 
 
 enormous treasure in gold. See Herod, 
 vii. 27 sqq. and the commentators. 
 
 '*" Athen. vii. p. 272 E, Plutarch 
 Comp. Nic. et Crass, init. [See above, 
 p. 38, note b. — Transl.] 
 
 2 U
 
 658 LABOUR OF SLAVES 
 
 for traces of the humanity which their arts and their philosophy 
 would indicate ; and in the same manner that their treatment 
 of the female sex was^ with few exceptions, unworthy and 
 degrading, so by being habituated to slaves from early youth, 
 they had lost all natural feelings of sympathy towards them. 
 No philosopher of antiquity, not even Socrates, raises an 
 objection against the institution of slavery. Plato, in his 
 perfect State, only desires that no Grecians should be made 
 slaves. Aristotle founds the existing usage upon apparently 
 scientific principles. But who would not be willing to pardon 
 the ancients for their hard-heartedness in this point, which is 
 at variance neither with their morality, their religion, nor their 
 international law, if, after Christianity has extended the influ- 
 ence of milder feelings and dispositions, after slavery has been 
 denounced by all moral, religious, and international laws, the 
 nations of Europe felt no shame in again establishing the same 
 institution, and still bargain and stipulate for it in treaties of 
 peace ? 
 
 As was the case in Italy and Sicily, and has been also in 
 modern times, the insurrection of these hordes of slaves was in 
 Greece neither unfrequent nor unaccompanied with danger. 
 In a fragment of Posidonius, the continuer of the history of 
 Polybius, it is related that the mine slaves in Attica murdered 
 their guards, took forcible possession of the fortifications of 
 Sunium, and from this point ravaged the country for a con- 
 siderable time; an occurrence, which, if Atheneeus expresses 
 himself correctly, must be referred to the time of the first 
 Sicilian servile war, about the year of the city 620 (b.c. 134), 
 at which time the Romans were already in possession of that 
 island ^*^ It is, however, more probable that it belongs to the 
 end of the 91st Olympiad, about which time, during the war of 
 Decelea, more than 20,000 slaves, of whom the greater portion 
 were manual labourers, eloped from the Athenians^**. Yet at 
 that time Sunium could hardly have been a tenable position, as 
 Thucydides would not have failed to mention the capture of it 
 
 '*' Athen. iit sup. and Scliweighseuser's note. 
 '^2 Thncyd. vii. 27-
 
 IN TH& MINES. 659 
 
 by the slaves. It was first fortified in Olymp. 91, 4 (b.c. 413), 
 for the protection of the vessels employed in importing corn, 
 and probably after it had been recaptured from the slaves, 
 whose ravages could scarcely have lasted beyond a summer. 
 
 It should be also observed, that of the slaves who worked 
 in the mines, some belonged to the lessees, and for some a rent 
 (d7rocj)opa) was paid to the proprietor'", the maintenance being 
 provided by the person who hired them. The price of slaves 
 varied, according to their bodily and mental qualities, from half 
 a mina to 5 and 10 minas: a common mining-slave however did 
 not cost at Athens, as Barthelemy asserts, more than from 3 to 
 6 minas, but in the age of Xenophon and Demosthenes not 
 more than 125 to 150 drachmas^^\ When it is stated that Nicias 
 the son of Niceratus gave a talent for an overseer of his 
 mines'", we are to understand a person in whom he could 
 repose great confidence, and to whom he might entrust the 
 superintendence of the whole business, so as to be free from 
 the necessity of employing a tenant, in short, a person rarely 
 to be met with; from this therefore nothing can be inferred 
 with regard to the usual price. 
 
 Since then slaves were neither dear to purchase nor expen- 
 sive to maintain, the working of mines was facilitated by the 
 institution of slavery; but as, for the most part, compulsion was 
 the only incentive to labour, and little favour was ever shown to 
 the slaves, the art of mining was necessarily retarded, while the 
 small benefit it received from the exertions of free inspectors 
 or managers, could have been of little avail; and thus the 
 higher character which mining bears in modern times was then 
 altogether wanting. By the hiring of slaves the profit was dis- 
 tributed into various channels, and by this means persons who 
 otherwise would have been unable to advance capital sufficient 
 for so expensive an undertaking, were enabled to engage in this 
 business. 
 
 ^"3 Andocid, de Myst. p. 19. 
 
 ^^■^ This may be obtained by compu- 
 tation from Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 23, 
 and by an obvious inference fiom De - 
 mosth. c. Pantsen. p. 976. The latter 
 
 passage has been quoted before. Con- 
 cerning the different prices of slaves, 
 see b. i. ch. 13. 
 
 '^* Xenoph. Socr. Mem. ii. 5, 2. 
 
 2 U 2
 
 660 
 
 LABOUR OF SLAVES 
 
 Many persons had a considerable number of slaves in the 
 mines. Nicias the celebrated general (and not the younger 
 Nicias, as has been erroneously supposed) had 1000 slaves 
 there; Hipponicus the third, the son of Callias the torchbearer, 
 600; Philemonides, 300; and others according to their circum- 
 stances' ^^ These wealthy and distinguished persons let their 
 mines to contractors, who were either poor citizens, isoteles, 
 freedmen, or resident aliens ^''^^ or perhaps not unfrequently 
 slaves belonging to the proprietors themselves, upon the con- 
 dition that the tenant should maintain the slaves, and pay an 
 obolus a day for each, free from all deduction, and should return 
 the full number which he had received. Thus Nicias received 
 from Sosias the Thracian one mina and two-thirds a day, Hippo- 
 nicus one mina, Philemonides half a mina. According to Xeno- 
 phon many slaves in the mines were in his time let upon the 
 same conditions'*^. 
 
 It does not appear probable that a rent of so considerable 
 an amount should have been paid for the slaves alone. Xeno- 
 phon, in stating the annual profit of 6000 mining-slaves, sup- 
 poses 360 days of labour, distributing the intercalary month 
 through the several years, and only deducting five holidays. If 
 however we reckon 350 days, and take 140 drachmas as the 
 average price of a oommon mining-slave, each slave would have 
 produced a return of nearly 50 per cent. (47ii) of his value; 
 which, when compared with the far inferior profit derived from 
 more valuable slaves skilled in some mechanical art, is out of all 
 proportion, though these latter were also supplied by their pro- 
 prietors w^ith the raw materia^''^ And although the masters 
 were without doubt paid for the goods thus furnished, yet the 
 procuring them required an outlay of capital, the profit on 
 which was also to be replaced. Are we to suppose that a 
 worker of mines like Sosias the Thracian would not have been 
 more willing to borrow a sum of money for the purpose of buy- 
 
 '** Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 14, and 
 thence Athen. vi. p. 272 E. 
 '■'^ Cf. Xenoph. ut sup. 4, 22. 
 i« Ut Slip. 4, 16. 
 
 ''^ Demosth. c. Aphob. i. p. 816, 
 ^sch. c. Timarch. p. 118, which pas- 
 sages are examined more at length in 
 b.i. ch. 13 (above p. 6.0).
 
 IN THE MINES. 
 
 661 
 
 ing slaves, than to pay away their whole value in the space of 
 two years in the shape of rent ? If he was able to hire slaves 
 by giving security, he would have been able to find sureties for 
 a sum of money. The profit upon slaves must indeed have 
 been much higher than upon monied capital, as the proprietor 
 lost unless both capital and interest were replaced before their 
 death; and the usual rate of interest being 12 per cent., slaves 
 must have produced more than this percentage; but how wide 
 is the difference between 14 or 15 per cent, and nearly 50? Is 
 it not then more probable that Nicias and others, who let slaves 
 in the mines upon these terms, received an obolus a head not for 
 the slaves alone, but for the mines also in which they worked? 
 An instance of a lease of a mine jointly with the slaves occurs 
 in the speech against Pantsenetus; thirty slaves, together with 
 a workshop, were let for the interest of 105 minas; but the 
 transaction was in fact only fictitious, as the money was in 
 reality lent upon the slaves alone, as will be presently shown: 
 but any fictitious transaction of this sort must have been 
 founded on a real custom. 
 
 Are we not also told that Nicias was possessed of several 
 mines? Plutarch indeed remarks'^'' that he had wasted his pro- 
 perty in this hazardous business; but it is not possible to refer 
 his statement to the letting of slaves, as in that trade no hazard 
 could have existed, the person who hired them being always 
 bound to return the same number that he received, and to pro- 
 vide sureties for the fulfilment of this obligation. To what pur- 
 pose again did Nicias purchase an inspector of the mines at the 
 price of a talent, if he did not work them at his own expense? 
 He is even said to have maintained a diviner, and to have sacri- 
 ficed daily for the success of his mines, and procured numerous 
 gangs of slaves, with the sole object of employing them for his 
 own profit. The management of them however would naturally 
 have been troublesome to the anxious disposition of Nicias, 
 occupied as he was with both civil and military concerns, and 
 he therefore divested himself of this care by letting both his 
 mines and slaves; a supposition which is at least more probable 
 
 "° Nic. 4 and Comp. Nic. et Ciuss. in init.
 
 662 PIIOFITS DERIVED FROM 
 
 and simple than that to which we are driven if it is rejected; 
 viz. that Nicias kept a hundred slaves for hire in addition to 
 those who worked in his own mines. According to the former 
 hypothesis, some part of the rent, which amounted to nearly 
 10 talents a year, must be considered as proceeding from the 
 mines. Xenophon, when he proposes that the state should 
 derive similar advantages from the letting of slaves, probably 
 implies that it should be connected with the letting of such 
 mines as were still unalienated, in which it is evident that the 
 lessee who obtained the metal also paid the rent in silver, which 
 Nicias and the other slave-proprietors would doubtless have 
 demanded from their tenants. 
 
 § 11. Profits derived from the Working of the Mines. 
 
 So long as the rich ores were not exhausted, the working was 
 extremely profitable to the possessors, especially as the prices 
 of provisions were very low in comparison with that of silver. 
 
 Although after the death of Niceratus, who inherited from 
 his father Nicias, less property is said to have been found than 
 was expected, his father was considered as one of the most 
 wealthy citizens : the property of Diphilus, another mine pro- 
 prietor, who indeed encroached illegally upon the supports of 
 the mines, amounted, at the time that it was confiscated, to 160 
 talents'''; an amount of property which for Athens and the age 
 of Lycurgus is very considerable; and when the possessions of 
 Diphilus were in his own hands, they were no doubt still larger, 
 for confiscated property seldom came into the public cofi*ers 
 without suffering some diminution, or being wastefully sold 
 under its proper price. Callias (a person of mean extraction, 
 and not of the celebrated family of Phsenippus), who out of 
 love for the sister and wife of Cimon paid Miltiades' fine of 
 
 151 Vit. Dec. Orat. in Plutarch, vol. ; the most approved statements. The 
 vi. p. 252. Of the property of Diphi- | words in the text, rj as rives fxvav, do 
 Ills each citizen received 50 drachmas, ' not deserve any consideration, wliether 
 which supposes a number of 19,200 j they are interpolated or genuine. 
 
 citizens, thus completely agreeing with I
 
 WORKING THE MINES. 
 
 663 
 
 50 talents, had also derived his wealth from the mines'"; and 
 the Callias who discovered the method of preparing cinnabar^ 
 was perhaps his grandson, having been, as is manifest from this 
 fact, personally engaged in the working of mines, and conse- 
 quently cannot have been the extravagant Callias, the son of 
 Hipponicus, nor was he at all connected with this noble family, 
 as Schneider appears to suppose. 
 
 We must not, on the other hand, be surprised, if, in subse- 
 quent times, especially when the quality of the ores had been 
 impoverished, many proprietors of mines suffered severe losses, 
 particularly when it is remembered that the working of mines 
 was rendered difficult by the want of gunpowder, that the 
 machinery was imperfect and scanty, and that the management 
 of the foundries was so defective that much metal was lost in 
 smelting. At the time when Xenophon wrote his Treatise upon 
 the Revenue, the greater number of the mine proprietors were 
 beginners, who were unable, from want of capital, to open new 
 mines, like the former possessors, though this practice was still 
 allowed by the legal conditions^"; the proprietors were never- 
 theless at that time increasing their number of slaves^**. Not 
 long afterwards, however, in the time of Demetrius Phalereus, 
 there was no want of willingness to devote capital and trouble 
 to the working of the mines; they mined with so much eager- 
 ness, says Demetrius, that they thought they would fetch up 
 Pluto himself; but they generally failed to obtain what they 
 sought for, and what they already had they lost^"; at last there- 
 fore they entirely gave up all farther excavation, and only made 
 use of the scoriae and the rejected stones. 
 
 Besides the necessary importation of timber, for which the 
 ports of Thoricus and Anaphlystus and the two harbours of 
 
 152 Plut. Cim. 4, Nepos Cim. 1. For 
 Schneider's opinion see his note upon 
 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 15. 
 
 1*3 Xenoph. ut sup. 4, 28. 
 
 154 Ibid. 4, 4. 
 
 155 See Demetrius, and from him 
 Posidonius ap. Strab, iii. p. 101 , Athen. 
 vi. p. 233 D, cf. Diod. v. 37. The 
 
 expression of Demetrius contains an 
 enigma, like the Homeric riddle. See 
 the commentators upon the author 
 just mentioned, particularly Casaubon 
 upon Strabo ; but as the enigma can- 
 not be solved, I have only been able to 
 give the approximate sense of the
 
 664 PROFITS DERIVED FROM WORKING THE MINES. 
 
 Sunium were employed, the expenses of mining were enhanced 
 in bad seasons by the high prices of corn. Upon most regions 
 which abound in ore nature has laid the curse of sterility**®; and 
 thus Athens^ as being the market of Greece, was in its flourishing 
 times supplied with corn by importation; but when it was 
 l)lockaded by sea, which frequently took place after the loss of 
 its ascendancy, or if prices were raised by a general failure in 
 the crops, the mine proprietors were the severest sufferers, as 
 they had to maintain large establishments of slaves. The 
 medimnus of corn sold at Athens in the time of Solon for a 
 drachma; in the time of Socrates and Aristophanes the common 
 price was from 2 to 3, and in that of Demosthenes from 5 to 6 
 drachmas; but in later times prices advanced so greatly that 
 barley sold for 18 drachmas'": at this juncture even those 
 mine proprietors were distressed for money, who before had 
 contrived to carry on their business with profit, and they are 
 said to have received assistance from the state; but we are not 
 informed in what manner* *^ We hear however of mines being 
 confiscated about this time'^®; the cause of which doubtless 
 was, that the possessors were unable to fulfil their obligations 
 to the state; while, as the author of the speech against Phee- 
 nippus says, the agricultural classes were making undue profits. 
 
 § 12. Some Legal Regulations respecting the Mines. 
 
 Lastly, we may consider some legal regulations respecting the 
 possession of mines. 
 
 As the ownership of the mines was vested in the people, no 
 compartment of a mine could be worked without information 
 being given to the public officers; and if this was not done, the 
 party offending was subject to a public action for not having 
 registered his mine {aypdcpov fieiaXkov BUtj)^^'^; the action 
 
 ' '" The ancients cite the instances I "' Orat. c. Phcenipp. p. 1039, 18, p. 
 
 of Thasos (see Archilochus quoted by 1044, ad fin. p. 1045, init. p. 1048, ad 
 
 the interpreters of Herod. N-i. 46), and fin. See b. i. eh. 15. 
 
 Hispania Felix: in which few places | '*« Ibid. p. 1048, 27. 
 
 made an exception. Pliu. xxxiii. 21, j '*^ Ibid. p. 1039, 20 sqq. 
 
 Strabo iii. p. 146. . I '*" Suidas and Zonaras in v. oypa^ou
 
 LEGAL REGULATIONS. 
 
 665 
 
 however could be also commenced by referring the matter to 
 the public assembly (tt/jo/SoX?;)'"'. Any person buying a share 
 from the state upon the legal conditions was bound to pay the 
 purchase money at the appointed time; if he exceeded his 
 term, he was subject to the common proceedings against public 
 debtors, and therefore to infamy, to imprisonment, and to a 
 fine of double the amount''^; and if the debt thus doubled was 
 not paid, to forfeiture of property, the debt being also inherited 
 by the children until the payment of the fine. If a mine pro- 
 prietor did not pay the rent in silver, the farmer-general was of 
 course empowered to institute a public suit against him. There 
 must however have been this difference between the methods 
 of proceeding against a mine proprietor and a public debtor, 
 that in the former case the community only laid claim to the 
 mine for which the twenty-fourth was in arrear, and not to the 
 whole property of the defaulter; while the obligation to pay the 
 purchase money fell upon the person of the buyer, and by that 
 means upon his whole property; there can therefore be no 
 doubt that if the rent fell in arrear, the defaulter was not liable 
 to the penalty of imprisonment. The speech against Phaenippus 
 furnishes a satisfactory example of the confiscation of a mine, 
 in which several persons had a share, without the other pro- 
 perty of the proprietors being forfeited to the state'"; for the 
 person in whose name this speech was composed, possessed 
 other property besides that which was forfeited, which he offers 
 to exchange with Pheenippus; and what is more, he had other 
 mines^^*, which were not forfeited to the state when the former 
 mine was confiscated. It was only in the case of peculiarly 
 
 ^UTaS\ov hiKT] : Ei Tty ovv edoKci \dBpa 
 epyd^eaOoL fieraWov, rbv firi drroypa- 
 yjrdfievov (^r]v rw (BovXofieva ypd(f)ea6ai 
 
 ^^' See Taylor, Preface to Demosth. 
 against Meidias, who states this from a 
 Cambridge manuscript, which contains 
 additions to Hai-pocration. [The ma- 
 nuscript has been published by Mr. 
 Dobree at the end of his edition of 
 Photius; and the whole article here 
 
 alluded to is in p. 676, as follows: 
 Upo^oKr] : (f)av€pov /xev rivos \av6dvov- 
 Tos di p.r]w(TLS' KeKTjXios (KaLKiXios) de 
 (Prjcriu (Ivai fju Kara touv drjixocna fieraX- 
 
 Xa VTTopvTTOvroiv dnocfiepovai 
 
 be Ka\ KudoXov tS)v ret KOivd kXctttov- 
 T(oV KoXe^adai 6e ovtcos koL tcis efiiro- 
 pUas p,Tjvu(r€is- — Traxsl.1 
 
 ^6^ Demosth. in Pantsen. p. 973. 
 
 ^"3 P. 1039, 22. 
 
 ^^* See p. 1044.
 
 666 LEGAL REGULATIONS 
 
 aggravating circumstances that the state could inflict severer 
 punishment upon persons who failed to pay their rent; for, 
 from the nature of suits of this description^ the assignment of 
 the penalty rested with the judges. 
 
 In all cases connected with mines, if it appeared that the 
 state had been injured, the mode of proceeding was by a public 
 action, and generally a phasis, which was the form when the 
 injury received had reference to the harbours, to embezzlement, 
 or detention of public property, to custom duties and other 
 taxes, or to sycophancy, and the defrauding of orphans, who 
 were under the immediate protection of the government'^\ An 
 oflfence which was especially liable to this method of prosecu- 
 tion was the undermining of or encroachment upon the sup- 
 ports^^% which considerably endangered the security of the 
 mines, and also displaced the boundaries. Now the law had 
 not appointed any definite punishment for a large portion of the 
 pubhc offenders, which was particularly the case in all offences 
 prosecuted by phasis; but the accuser fixed the penalty in the 
 memorial which he presented, and the defendant made a 
 counter-assessment {avTirt/jbrjcris), on which the court exercised 
 its discretion, without being bound by the amount of penalty 
 fixed upon by the litigant parties; the punishment assigned 
 might however be either death, fine, infamy, or banishment; 
 e.g., Diphilus was punished with death, and his property con- 
 fiscated, for some oflfence connected with the mines. The 
 phasis, according to Pollux, was brought before the archon, by 
 which we are to understand the archon Eponymus. This archon 
 however was not the president of the court [rfye/jbcov BcKacrTrj- 
 plov) in mining cases: we must therefore either assume that if 
 a phasis was instituted, it was first brought before the archon 
 Eponymus, who then referred it to the tribunal in which the 
 supreme jurisdiction was lodged; or we must limit the assertion 
 of Pollux to the phasis in cases of orphans^ ^'property, which 
 
 ^"5 Pollux viii. 47, Epitome of Har- ; 315. 
 pocration quoted by the commentators j '®° Lex. Seg. p. 315, ^a.(Tis : fxTjwa-is 
 upon Pollux, Etymol. Photius, and j Trpos rovs (ipxovTas Kara rSiV viropv-rrov- 
 Suidas, in v. (jidcis, Lex, Seg. p. 313, ! rmv to peToWov. Cf. Phot, ut sup.
 
 R-ESPECTING THE MIXES. 
 
 667 
 
 were certainly introduced by the archon Eponymus'". All 
 mining cases^ whether proceeded in by phasis or by any other 
 method, were introduced by the thesmothet^e**^ The court 
 appointed for such causes is called by a grammarian the 
 mining court'^^. 
 
 The speech against Pantsenetus is a paragraphe against a 
 mining action; from this it is evident that a suit like that insti- 
 tuted by Pantsenetus as a mining case belonged to the monthly 
 causes {efi/jLrjvoL StVat)'^% that is to say, it was necessary that 
 judgment should be given within a month; the object being no 
 doubt that the mine proprietor might not be too long detained 
 from his business, a preference which was allowed to the mining 
 cases as well as to the proceedings in commercial causes 
 {ifiiropLKoX hlKai), and to litigation concerning dowries and 
 between eranistse (ipaviKal Blkui)^^^: in commercial cases how- 
 ever, and probably in all others, this regulation was not intro- 
 duced till after the date of Xenophon's Essay on the Revenue, 
 in which it was proposed that a more rapid progress should be 
 allowed to commercial suits: in the time of Philip the monthly 
 causes are mentioned as if they had not been previously in 
 existence, and were then but lately introduced^ ^^ 
 
 Among the SUaL fieraWcKal were included all suits which 
 related to the mines, and particularly to the mining companies, 
 and whatever else was mentioned in the mining law (fieraX^ 
 \lko<; vofMosY''^, Concerning this law we have no satisfactory 
 account; there are only four heads of which we have any 
 information, namely, of encroachment, of expulsion from the 
 business, of arson, and of armed attack; the two latter were 
 without doubt always the subjects of a public action, and the 
 first might certainly take this form of proceeding, if public 
 property was encroached upon; but it is by no means true that 
 
 • 167 Pollux viii. 89, &:c. i 
 
 ^68 Demosth. c. Pantsen. p. 976, 18, 
 Pollux viii/ 88. 
 
 169 MeTaXkiKov^^iKao-TTjpiov, in the 
 argnment to the speech against Pantte- 
 netus, p. 965, 24. 
 
 170 Demosth. c. Pantsen. p. 966, 17- 
 
 171 Pollux viii. 63, 101, Harpoc. and 
 
 Said, in v. efjLfXTjvoi dUai, Lex. Seg. p. 
 237. 
 
 '7* Xenoph. de Vectig. 3, Orat. pro 
 Haloneso, p. 79, 18 sqq. 
 
 17^ The only passage on the subject 
 of the /xeraXXtKat dUai is in Demosth. 
 c. Pautaen. p. 976, 977.
 
 66S 
 
 LEGAL REGULATIONS 
 
 all mining causes were brought on as public actions. If De- 
 mosthenes expresses himself correctly, the law was divided into 
 these four parts alone '^■'; but cases which referred to the mining 
 companies belonged also to the mining suits'^*, and as these 
 four heads contain nothing of the kind, we are compelled to 
 suppose that the enactments concerning encroachment and 
 expulsion from labour mainly referred to partners in the same 
 mine divided into different workshops. It is certain from the 
 speech against Panteenetus that private suits between mine 
 proprietors and other private individuals, which referred not to 
 mining, but to any general question of law, with which a mine 
 was incidentally connected, were not of the number of mining 
 cases; as, for example, if a law suit arose for a sum of money 
 lent upon a mine; it is evident indeed that such would neces- 
 sarily be the case. Moreover the actions for not registering a 
 mine, and non-payment of the entrance money and the rent of 
 the twenty-fourth, did not belong to the mining causes, nor 
 were they mentioned in the mining law: the first doubtless fell 
 under the head of embezzlement of public property; the second 
 was determined by the laws respecting the pubhc debtors; the 
 third was decided according to the laws relating to the farming 
 of the revenue {po/jlol reKwviKol), and accordingly the phasis 
 could in such a case be instituted. 
 
 The clause in the mining law which prohibited the pro- 
 prietor from working outside his own boundary, or carrying an 
 adit into another compartment' ^% does not require any farther 
 
 '''* Ibid. p. 976, 27,-977, 9. 
 
 '-'"> Ibid. p. 977,20. 
 
 ^^^ The words in the text are eVt- 
 KaTarefiveLV tcov fierpoiv evTos, p. 977, 
 10. It has been thought preferable to 
 write €KTbs, which certainly makes the 
 sense clearer, but is still an improbable 
 correction. Evtos appears, like the 
 ciira of the Romans, to mean both in- 
 side and outside, according as the spec- 
 tator adopts his station, as Herodotus 
 (iii. 116) says evrbs divepyovTai : they 
 exclude without in reference to us, but 
 within in reference to the countries 
 
 which exclude. Thus emKaTarefiveiv 
 euros TCOV fierpcov means to cut outside 
 your own boundaries, but inside the 
 boundaries of those whose property is 
 invaded. Another expression for trans- 
 gressing the boundaries occurs in p. 
 977, in the words rols erepov (/iie'raX- 
 \ov?) (rvvTpr)(Tacnv els tcitwv ttXtjctIov. 
 Whether the words els ra raiv TvKrjalov 
 should be struck out is difficult to de- 
 cide. [See Wordsworth, Athens and 
 Attica, ch. 2f{, on the OopUioi ^ 5io- 
 pxjTTiDv of Autiphanes. — Transl.J
 
 RESPECTING THE MIXES. 
 
 669 
 
 explanation, of which however the other three stand in need; of 
 these one clause relates to persons driving out a mining pro- 
 prietor from his business (i^elXkovaLv eK rrj? ipyaalas). Ex- 
 pulsion (i^ovXTj) is the term in the Athenian law for obtaining 
 possession of another person^s property, when wrongfully taken 
 from the legal possessor; and probably it was only used in 
 reference to immoveables^". The action brought by the injured 
 party in such a case as this was called the Slkt) i^ovXrjs; the 
 same form could also be adopted if a man was interrupted in 
 the enjoyment of what he had bought, i.e. taken, from the state, 
 or was obstructed in the prosecution of his business^ ^^ Again, 
 if any person was declared by judicial decision to be the rightful 
 possessor, by which he obtained permission to seize the pro- 
 perty of his antagonist, and was obstructed in the seizure by 
 the resistance of the actual possessor, this was considered an 
 act of expulsion just as much as the non-payment of a debt by 
 a private individual to his creditor at the appointed term : in 
 both cases the Slkt] i^ovXij^ equally obtained' '^ But even 
 without the authority of a judicial decision, the creditor had a 
 right of seizure over the mortgaged property, whether moveable 
 or immoveable, as soon as the term of payment had expired ; 
 and if any resistance was made to him in the exercise of this 
 right, the BIkt} e^ovXT)^ might also be instituted, the mortgaged 
 property being considered as his own, as soon as the time had 
 
 '77 According to Hudtwalcker (von 
 den Diateten, p. 135) who goes upon the 
 authority of Suidas,on moveable property 
 as well. But the action for the forcible 
 abstraction of moveable property was 
 the Si'kt; ^Laitov. It is therefore pro- 
 bable that the diKrj €^ovX7]s only affected 
 moveables when it was an actio rei ju- 
 dicatce, and when the mortgagee was 
 obstructed in the exercise of the right 
 of seizure upon moveable property. 
 See book iii. ch. 12. 
 
 178 Pollux viii. 59, 17 be r»)y e^ovXrjs 
 8lkt] yiyverai, orav Tis rbv e/c brjixocrlov 
 Trpidfjievov p; ea KapnovaOac a enplaTo. 
 
 Kai an epya- 
 (ocTLv 6 v6p.os 
 
 Suidas in e^ovXrjs 8ikt) 
 cnas bk ei tis e'lpyoLTO, I 
 biKaCea-dai npus top Hpyovra e^ovXrjs. 
 
 '79 The exercise of the right of sei- 
 zure upon immoveables and ships is 
 generally called ep^areveiv : but in the 
 case of slaves or other moveable pro- 
 perty this expression could not be 
 employed. Of the right of seizure by 
 a judicial verdict, and of the dUr) e^ov- 
 \r]s for not paying a fine {actio rei ju- 
 dicata), see Hudtwalcker, von den 
 Diateten, p. 134 sqq.; and with refe- 
 rence to the decisions of the diaetetae 
 and arbitrators, pp. 152, 183.
 
 670 
 
 LEGAL REGULATIONS 
 
 expired in which his claims should have been satisfied'^". In 
 like manner a hUj] i^ovXrj^ could be brought on^ if one party- 
 asserted that he had purchased anything and laid claim to it on 
 that ground, while another party claimed it as mortgagee'^'; 
 where this method of proceeding would naturally be allowed to 
 the creditor as illegally deprived of his mortgage, if the purchaser 
 did not recognise his title. 
 
 Expulsion from a mine might, therefore, be considered 
 either as a seizure or retention of property, or as obstruction 
 in the use of property purchased from the state, and as an 
 impediment in the prosecution of the business. As, however, 
 the mining law contained separate provisions upon this point, 
 expulsion from a mine must have been forbidden under severer 
 sanctions than from other property, or there must have been 
 particular privileges granted to the mine proprietors against 
 persons who by the general law would have been authorized to 
 take possession of their mines. It appears to me probable, 
 that a creditor, who lent money upon mortgage on a mine, 
 could not, as in the case of other mortgaged property, make 
 
 ^^ That the creditor had the right 
 of taking possession of the security, 
 after the expiration of the term of 
 payment, without a judicial decision, as 
 Sahnasius (de M. U. cap. 13) assumes, 
 can hardly be denied. This is clearly 
 shown by an instance in Demosth. c. 
 Apatur. p. 894, 5, erv^e 5e ovroal 
 6(p€iXa>v €7rt rfj vrjl t^ avrov reTTapd- 
 Kovra fivas, Koi ol xRW^f^i- naTfjTreiyov 
 avTov aTraiTovvTes, kol eve^drevov els 
 TTjv vavv elXr)(p6T€S rfj V7reprjfiepia,where 
 there is no question of any previous 
 judicial decision. The passage of the 
 Etymologist in v. ip.^arevcrat. is not 
 decisive; but Suidas in v. e^ovkijs 
 plainly distinguishes the diKT] e^ovXrjs 
 which was founded upon a judicial 
 verdict, from the suit which the cre- 
 ditor instituted on being obstructed in 
 the exercise of the right of seizure: 
 c6i/cd^ero Se Kui e^ovXrjs Koi 6 XPW'^'V^ 
 
 KaT^X^LV eTTlX^lpOiV KTT]p.a TOV XP^^O" 
 TOVVTOi KOL KCoXvOfieVOS VTTO TLVOS. In 
 
 the agreement of bottomry in Demosth. 
 c. Lacrit. p. 926, the nght of seizing 
 the goods without a judicial verdict is 
 granted in a separate clause. Seizure 
 for debt without a judicial decision 
 occurs in the Clouds of Aristophanes, 
 vs. 34. 
 
 *^^ Pollux viii. 95, kol fifjv, el 6 fieu 
 ct)S eayvrjfxevos dfi^iafi-qTa. Krrjp.aTos, 6 
 be cos VTVoOrjKrjv excoVj e^ovXrjs r) diKT]. 
 I do not perceive what is the obscm-ity 
 which Hudtwalcker (von den Diateten, 
 p. 143) finds in these words. It may 
 be observed that the same sense is 
 contained in the words of Suidas just 
 quoted, only that Pollux expresses 
 himself more generally, KwXvofxevos imo 
 Tivos. This t\s is in our case the 
 dfi<pi(r^T]Tcov cos €covr]p.€uos-
 
 RESPECTING THE MINES. 6?! 
 
 use of the right of seizure without the decision of a court of 
 justice; and that if he ventured to attempt it without such 
 authority, the debtor could institute the hUr] e^ovkrjs against 
 him. For we find that in cases of money lent upon mines, the 
 mines were not given simply in mortgage, as other landed 
 property, but the creditor was instated as legal possessor by a 
 fictitious sale for the amount of the sum lent, and the debtor 
 was considered as the tenant of the mine upon paying the 
 interest of the principal. 
 
 Mnesicles had bought from Pantsenetus, the son of Tele- 
 machus, a mine together with the slaves belonging to it : 
 Mnesicles was properly the creditor of Pantaenetus, but he is 
 represented as proprietor of the mine. For when Euergus and 
 Nicobulus engaged to lend money to Pantsenetus upon this 
 mine, Mnesicles and not Pantsenetus transferred it to them as 
 vendor ; Euergus and Mnesibulus then became the proprietors, 
 and let the mine and slaves to Pantsenetus, fixing the interest 
 of the principal as a fictitious rent, and appointing a term for 
 the payment of the money and the conclusion of the pur- 
 chase^ ^^ Pantsenetus afterwards, wishing to satisfy Euergus 
 and Nicobulus, the purchasers, to whom Pantsenetus next 
 transferred the mine, were willing to take it upon the condition 
 that the two former should call themselves the vendors of the 
 mine and the slaves ^^\ In no place is there the slightest 
 indication that this formality so frequently repeated, was at all 
 unusual or surprising. To what purpose would have been all 
 these tedious proceedings, if a mortgagee had the right of seizing 
 the mortgaged mine without a judicial decision, and could 
 institute a ZUri i^ovKt)^ against the debtor for obstruction in 
 the seizure ? If, however, the creditor had no right of seizure 
 upon the mine, prudence required that he should call himself 
 the purchaser, in order to have a better legal title to the 
 possession of the mortgaged property, and not to suffer his 
 claims to be dependant upon the uncertainty of a judicial 
 
 182 Demosth. c. Pantsen. p. 967. i by Heraldus Anim. in Salmas. Obser. 
 
 183 Ibid. p. 970, 971, 975. An ex- ad I. A. et R. iv. 3. 
 planation of the whole case is given I
 
 6/2 
 
 LEGAL REGULATIONS 
 
 decision. Many reasons can be thought of why a preference of 
 this kind should have been granted to the mines in regard to 
 mortgage debts ; for example, that the mine proprietor, after 
 having incurred much expense without any return, might not 
 be subsequently deprived of it against his will, just at the time 
 when he was beginning to reap the fruits of his exertions ; or 
 else that the working of the mines might not be interrupted to 
 the prejudice of the state by a seizure of this kind. It hardly 
 requires the authority of Demosthenes^^" to state, that expulsion 
 from the lease of a mine taken by one individual proprietor 
 from another, also authorized the institution of a hLKrj e^ovKr}^, 
 as it was obstructing the proprietor in the prosecution of his 
 business. 
 
 The two other heads of the mining law are very obscure. 
 By arson, or under-burning, which is the exact meaning of the 
 Greek expression [eav v(f)dyfrrj Tt9)'^% we might either under- 
 stand the burning of the wood used for supporting the mine ; 
 or the setting fire to the ores (a practice which was well known 
 to the ancients), for the purpose of undermining the pillars 
 which supported the overlying mass, after they had become 
 infirm. To what the prohibition referred of attacking the 
 miners with arms, and what could have been the reason of it, 
 cannot be now ascertained; so far, however, is certain, that 
 armed attack is meant, and not the seizure of the tools or 
 instruments, as Petit imagines '^^ 
 
 One of the chief preferences enjoyed by the mine proprie- 
 tors, was the immunity from taxes, which the laws had allowed 
 
 '«* Ibid. p. 968, 6, and p. 974. An 
 instance of the expulsion of a proprie- 
 tor and not of a mere sub-tenant, was 
 contained in the oration against Mecy- 
 tlius. See Dionys. ut sup. note 101. 
 
 ^8-^ Demosth. ut sup. p. 977, 7. 
 Upon the practice of setting fire to 
 the ores as used by the ancients, 
 besides Reitemeier and others, Ameil- 
 hon as above p. 490 sqq. may be con- 
 sulted. 
 
 »«« In the first law Petit (Leg. Att. 
 
 vii. 12) also supposes that the cham- 
 bering and the pillars of the mines ai'e 
 meant, but expresses himself in a 
 singular manner. The words, av onXa 
 €7ri<f)epT], he alters by a most absurd 
 correction : AVesseling ha^ already 
 remarked that arms are meant from 
 the words, ttXt^v et firj tovs KOfML^ofxivovs, 
 a TrpoelvTo croi, /xeB' onXoiv rJKeiv vofxi- 
 ^€Ls. Petit's whole article upon the 
 mining law is as ill executed as most 
 of the other parts of his work.
 
 RESPECTING THE MINES. 673 
 
 to property vested in the mines '^^ The fact itself is unques- 
 tionable ; but as it occurs in the speech against Phsenippus, in 
 which mention is made of the relief which the state had granted 
 to the mine proprietors, it might be thought that nothing 
 more was meant than a temporary alleviation for the year in 
 which they had sustained a severe loss ; a supposition which 
 would apparently be confirmed by the assertion of iEschines^®% 
 that Timarchus had sold his estates, including two mines, in 
 order, by the concealment of his property, to withdraw himself 
 from the obligation of serving the liturgies. But as ^schines 
 is not accustomed to weigh his words with great exactness, the 
 fear of the liturgies entertained by Timarchus perhaps extended 
 only to his other estates, together with which his mines were 
 only accidentally mentioned ; and even if mines did not oblige 
 the possessor to perform liturgies, yet the possession of them 
 strongly confirmed the idea entertained of a man^s wealth, and 
 the public opinion on this subject had no inconsiderable influ- 
 ence upon his nomination to the performance of liturgies. 
 
 In the speech against Pheenippus, however, the orator would 
 not have omitted to remark that the immunity from taxes 
 enjoyed by the mines was only introduced a short time before 
 for the purpose of relieving the possessors, if such had been 
 the case; for as the complainant is particularly earnest in claim- 
 ing the good will of the people towards the mine proprietors, it 
 would have exactly suited his object to mention the preference 
 recently shown to them ; but instead of this, he speaks in a 
 general manner of the laws by which immunity had been 
 granted to the possessors of mines. It is necessary therefore 
 to consider the exemption of the mines from property taxes 
 and liturgies, as estabhshed by laws of ancient standing: but 
 whether intended as an encouragement to mining, is another 
 question. Are we to suppose that the people of Athens, from 
 no other motive than that of favouring a particular department 
 of industry, would have exempted a large number of their citi- 
 zens from all liturgies and taxes for property vested in mines, 
 including moreover the trierarchy, from which no one with the 
 
 '^' Orat. c. PhEenipp. p. 1044, 17. '°' C. Timarch. p. 121. 
 
 2 X
 
 674 
 
 LEGAL REGULATIONS 
 
 exception of the nine archons had an absolute and personal 
 immunity^ ^*; while from the property taxes, at least according 
 to the statement of Demosthenes, no exemption ever existed? 
 What renders this the more improbable is, that a large portion 
 of the mine proprietors were extremely wealthy at certain 
 times : and that any person might, when he pleased, have with- 
 drawn himself from the public services, by purchasing and 
 working mines. 
 
 My opinion is that this immunity was conceded not as an 
 encouragement to mining and mine proprietors, but only upon a 
 legal principle. The mine proprietor was a tenant, who was 
 permitted the use of public property in consideration of the 
 payment of a sum of money, and of a portion of the yearly 
 produce as a fixed rent. But the property taxes and liturgies 
 only fell upon freehold property, while the mines, being con- 
 veyed by the people on condition that the tenants made an 
 annual payment to the state, were for this reason considered as 
 tax-free. 
 
 Whether slaves were included among the property vested 
 in mines, I do not venture to determine: there being however 
 no reason of any cogency why a tax should not have been 
 imposed upon them, it appears to me more probable that by 
 the property in the silver mines, we are only to understand the 
 mines belonging to a citizen. 
 
 A legal consequence of the exemption of the mines from 
 taxes was their exclusion from the property which was made 
 over in the Exchange (avrlBoacs)^^'^, Moveables and immove- 
 ables belonging to the two parties were conveyed in the 
 Exchange from one to the other, all such property being liable 
 to property taxes and liturgies, with the exception only of the 
 silver mines, which did not oblige the possessor to perform any 
 of these services. 
 
 '^^ A temporary exemption from 
 the trierarchy was allowed in certain 
 cases, e. g. orphans were exempt 
 
 during their minority, and for one year 
 over. 
 
 's'' Orat. c. Phgenipp. ut sup. See 
 book iv. ch. 16.
 
 RESPECTING THE MINES. 675 
 
 [There follows in the original an abstract of Xenophon's 
 proposals with respect to the silver mines in his Essay on the 
 Revenues. But as an account of this plan has been already 
 given at the end of the fourth book'^ the translator has omitted 
 it here, as a needless repetition. He will however take this 
 opportunity of offering a few remarks upon an argument 
 brought forward by Mr. Boeckh both in his Treatise on the 
 Prices of Slaves, and in the above Dissertation^. 
 
 It is stated by Xenophon to have been a common practice 
 in Attica, to let slaves to be employed in the mines at the rate 
 of an obolus a day for each. The proprietor therefore received 
 for one slave 350 oboli, or nearly 59 drachmas a year. Now 
 the selling price of mine-slaves appears, upon the author^s com- 
 putation, to have varied from 125 to 150 drachmas. " Conse- 
 quently," he says, " capital laid out in this manner produced an 
 annual return of nearly 50 per cent., a rate so disproportionate 
 to the profits obtained by other modes of investment, that the 
 statement of Xenophon must evidently have another meaning:" 
 and he ends by conjecturing, that the rent of the mine in which 
 the slaves worked was included in this payment of an obolus. 
 Now it should be observed that the passage of Xenophon is 
 both explicit and precise^, and therefore unless the obvious 
 meaning of the words leads to a complete absurdity, there is 
 strong reason for not acceding to this interpretation. Perhaps 
 however, if the circumstances of the letting are more closely 
 examined, the apparent difficulty may be diminished at least, if 
 not altogether removed. 
 
 A person engages to supply a large number of slaves for the 
 severest and most unwholesome* description of labour, and 
 always to keep that number complete. For this he must spe- 
 culate in slaves as a dealer speculates in horses ; he must pur- 
 
 ^ Above, p. 606. I o/3oXoi/ fxev dreXr] Udarov r^y rjnepas 
 
 2 Above, p. 73. dnodidovai, top 5' dpi3ix6v taovs del 
 
 3 Xenoph. de Vectig. 4, 14. 'Niklus l napexetv drap ri to. TroXaia M 
 
 TToW 6 NLKT)pdTov €KTr]aaTO iv Tols dp- j XeycLV ; Kol yap vvv noXkoi daiv iv rois 
 yvpeiois xiXt'ovs dvOpooTTOvs, ovs eKelvos j dpyvpeiois avBpoinoi ovtcos eKdidop-evou 
 ^coaia Tto QpuKi e^epiadoxrev, ecji <a | * Above, p. 636, 657- 
 
 2x2
 
 676 LEGAL REGULATIONS RESPECTING THE MINES. 
 
 chase large numbers with a certainty that many will be of very 
 inferior value to others; the sick, the weak, and the aged must 
 be maintained, when their labour is of little value. In Attica 
 moreover there was very considerable danger of the elopement 
 of slaves; and in time of war, when once lost, they could never 
 be recovered. On one occasion too the mine slaves mutinied 
 against their masters, and seized a neighbouring fortress, from 
 which they ravaged the country around for a whole summer; 
 and it is probable that, for this one successful, there were many 
 unsuccessful attempts. It is evident then that all these circum- 
 stances, by increasing the risk and expense, would also produce 
 an apparent increase in the amount of profits on capital thus 
 invested. 
 
 It would be easy to pursue the subject farther, and to cite 
 parallel cases of apparently high profits in modern times, when 
 indemnification for extraordinary danger or expense is required: 
 but until the author can bring stronger arguments in favour of 
 his conjecture, what has been said appears to be sufficient.]
 
 NOTE. 677 
 
 NOTE. 
 
 Since the publication of Professor Boeckh's Dissertation on the Laurian . 
 Mines, a more accurate description of the district has been given by Mr. Dod- 
 well in his Tour through Greece, from whose account the following notices are 
 extracted. 
 
 At a short distance from Thoricus, in his way from Athens, Mr. Dodwell 
 observes, " that in some places the road was elevated like a bank, and had the 
 appearance of being artificial ; great part of it being composed of scoria from 
 
 the silver mines of Laurion (vol. i. p. 534) One hour from Thorikos 
 
 brought us to one of the ancient shafts of the silver mines ; and a few hundred 
 yards further we came to several others, which are of a square form, and cut 
 in the rock. We observed only one round shaft, which was larger than the 
 the others, and of considerable depth, as we conjectured from the time that 
 the stones, which were thrown in, took to reach the bottom (p. 537). Near 
 this are the foundations of a large round tower, and several remains of ancient 
 walls, of regular construction. The traces are so extensive, that they seem to 
 indicate not only the buildings attached to the mines, but the town of Laurion 
 itself, which was probably strongly fortified, and inhabited principally by the 
 
 people belonging to the mines We observed several large heaps of 
 
 scoria scattered about (p. 538) We proceeded over the low part of 
 
 Laurion, and had some difficulty in finding the way to Sunium, to which there 
 was no regular track, &c. Travelling here by night would be attended with 
 almost certain destruction, owing to the numerous shafts, which, concealed by 
 the weeds and bushes, form a treacherous ambush by the way" (p. 539). 
 
 On his return from Sunium, Mr. Dodwell observed, not far from that place, 
 " a great quantity of scoria heaped up near the sea ; and a little further inland 
 the shaft of a mine.'' 
 
 Mr. Wordsworth likewise travelled across the district of the Laurion 
 mines, and has described it in his Athens and Attica, ch. 26'— 28. In ch. 27 he 
 says, "We now pass along the eastern shore towards Thoricos, now Therico. 
 The hills are scattered over with juniper bushes. The ground which we tread 
 is strewed with rusty heaps of scoria from the silver ore which once enriched 
 the soil. The silver source of these mines, which was once the treasury of the 
 land, is now dried up. On our left is a hill called Score, so named from these 
 heaps of scoria with which it is covered. Here the shafts which have been 
 sunk for working the ore are visible, from which the name of the country is 
 derived." And he adds in a note : " Aavpa, in ancient Greek, is a street or 
 lane ; Aavpelov, a place formed of such lanes ; i. e. a. mine of shafts, cut as it 
 were into streets like a catacomb." In ch. 28 he says, " Leaving this morning 
 the hut in which we were lodged at Thoricus, we enter a glen between jNIount 
 Kordra on the right and Mount Tibari on the left. The country becomes
 
 678 NOTE. 
 
 more cheerful as we approach the village of Keratid. Heaps of scoria still 
 occur near the road-side ; a peasant who accompanies us calls it by its ancient 
 name {anapia). These heaps suggest the meaning of the title of a lost comedy 
 by Antiphanes, which was inscribed QopUioL ^ dtopvTTcov. I conceive that 
 the Thoricians were satirized in that play, as guilty of unfair dealing, by 
 piercing through from their own into theii* neighbours' shafts in working their 
 mines for the ore, of which the scoria is now visible near their own village." 
 (See Meineke, Fragm. Com. Gr. vol. iii. p. 56.) 
 
 In support of the emendations of the passage of the Aristotelian (Economics 
 proposed by Professor Boeckh and Mr. Wordsworth (see p. 626, note 36) it 
 may be observed that the ores of this district have been ascertained to contain 
 lead as well as silver- The following passage is from Walpole's Memoirs 
 relating to Asiatic Turkey, p. 426 : — " When Mr. Hawkins was on his voyage 
 to the Euripus, he was detained by the Etesian winds many days on the coast of 
 Attica, and was enabled to make during that' time an accurate examina- 
 tion of the mining district. The result of this mineralogical survey was, the 
 discovery of the veins of argentiferous lead ore, with which that part of the 
 country seems to abound." See further Col. Leake's Demi of Attica, p. 65. — 
 Traxsl.
 
 INDEX. 
 
 Actors, gains of, 120 
 
 Additional payments, 342 
 
 ^Abvvaroi, 242 sqq. ; applied to pro- 
 perty, 544 
 
 vEgina, its area and slave population, 
 38, 39 ; Eicostologus there, 337 
 
 *Aei(f)vyia, 393 
 
 'A-yobi/ aTifiTjTos and rifirjrosj 371 
 
 Agonothetae, 216 
 
 * Ay opd, revenues from, 313 
 'AyopaTot, 313 
 ^Ayopavo^oiy 48, 333 
 "Aypacplov dUr], 349, 389 
 'Aypd(f>ov fxeraXXov dUrj, 664 
 Agyrrhius, 220, 223, 224, 228, 236, 
 
 316 sqq. 
 AlyiKopeis, 494 
 
 AiVetay dUrj, 352, 364, 372, 374 
 Alexander's plunder and revenues in 
 
 Asia, 11, 12 
 Alcibiades, treasurer on the Acropolis, 
 
 198 ; his assessment of the tributes, 
 
 401 ; his profligacy, 293; his property, 
 
 484 
 Alcmaeon, 7 ; his wealth, 476 
 Allies, dependent and independent, 403 
 'AXnyiov dUt], 193 
 "AXc^tra, 94, 96, 286 
 Altars, building of, 202, 385 
 Ammonis, 240 
 Amorgus, stuffs of, 105 
 
 * AfxcjiOTepoTrKovs, 133 
 Anaphlystus, a fortress, 202, 617, 619 
 ^ Ava7r6ypa(f)a, 337 
 
 ^Avaavvra^is, 511 
 
 Andocides, oration of, irepl Elprjvrjs not 
 
 spurious, 176; Andocides interpreted, 
 
 196 sq. ; explained and emended, 315 
 
 sqq. 
 ^AvdpanoBiapos, 409 
 'Ai'SpoX7;\//'ta, dvbpoXrjyjnov, 585 
 Androtion, 530 sq. 
 'Aj/Tiyoi/is, a sacred trireme, 240 
 ^AvTiypa(pr), 358 
 'Ai/rtypa^ely for the public money, 185 
 
 sq. 188; for distributions of corn, 89 
 
 'AvTidoa-is, 580 sq. 674 
 
 Antiochus the Great, 12 
 
 Antipater, regulation made by liim 
 concerning the rights of citizenship, 
 486, 535 
 
 Antiphon's orations concerning the 
 tribute of Samothrace and of Lindus, 
 413 sq.; Antiphon emended, 502; 
 interpreted, 406 
 
 *A7ray(oyr}, 352, 380 
 
 Aphidna, a fortress, 202 
 
 Apodectae, 1 59 sq. 
 
 'A7roypa(j)ai^ 510 
 
 'ATTo^opa, 72, 659 ; d7ro(f)opa of the al- 
 lies to the Lacedaemonians, 396 
 
 'ATToppTjTa, contraband articles, 53 
 
 'ATTOo-roXety, 543 
 
 'A7rdra|t$-, 414 
 
 'AnoTiiJiTjpa, 143 
 
 'Ap;tJ7, 158, 239 
 
 'ApXlT€KTCOV, 220 
 
 Architheoria, 214, 452 
 
 'ApxcovT]s,m5, 316,336 
 
 Archons, Athenian, mode of their no- 
 mination and qualifications requisite, 
 508 sqq. 
 
 Archons or governors of the Athe- 
 nians in the subject states, 406, 407 
 
 Area of Attica, 30, 31 
 
 Areopagus, 154, 189, 495 
 
 'Apyd8eis, 494 
 
 'Apyias diKT], 475 
 
 'ApyvpoXoyetv, 586 
 
 "Apyvpos and dpyvpiov, difference be- 
 tween, 23 
 
 Aristides, 165, 176; his assessment of 
 the tributes, 396 
 
 Aristophanes, property of, 458 
 
 Aristophanes the poet, Eq. I74, 1300, 
 p. 388, Vesp. 657, 298 ; Ecclesiazu- 
 sae illustrated, 493, 520 
 
 Aristotle,the (Economics incon-ectly at- 
 tributed to, 3,299, 587; emended, 300 
 
 Arms, prices of, 107 
 
 Arrhephoria, 452 
 
 Artabe, 93 
 
 Artemisium, battle of, 256 
 
 "Apros, 96, 97
 
 r>80 
 
 INDEX. 
 
 'Ao-f/Sfi'ay ypcKfyf), 380, 38-2 
 
 Assault, action for, 357 
 
 Asses, price of, 7-4 
 
 ^AcTTvvofioi, 204 
 
 Ast)Ta, mines of, 8 
 
 'A(7vyypa<f>ov, 128 
 
 ' AreXeia, 85 sqq. ; rov fiCTOiKLOv, 330 ; 
 from liturgies, 450 ; from the pro- 
 perty tax, 472 ; from the trierarchy, 
 544 sqq.; of the resident aliens, 538 ; 
 of the isoteles, 541 
 
 ' AreXavrjTa, 337 
 
 Athenians in Delos, 430 
 
 AthlothetiB, 215, 216 
 
 "Arifiia, 381, 390 sq. 
 
 Avreperai, 279 
 
 Automedon's decree for the Tenedians, 
 420 
 
 AvTOVonoi, 403 
 
 B. 
 
 Bankers, 126 sqq. 
 
 Baths, price of, 1 19 
 
 Beggary, unknown at Athens in its 
 best times, 486 
 
 Besa, 619, 620 
 
 Biaioiv diKT], 378 
 
 Birds, prices of, 102 
 
 B\a^r)s diKT], 371 
 
 Bond slaves, 70, 475, 494 
 
 Books, trade in, 47 
 
 BoSivai, 216 
 
 Bottomry, 131 sqq. 
 
 BovXcvaecos ypafprj, 349, 390 
 
 Bowmen, 208 sq. 264 sq. 
 
 Bread, 96, 97 
 
 Building, works of, undertaken by the 
 state, 201 sq. 
 
 Burials, expense of, 114, 214 
 
 Byssus, 104 
 
 Byzantium, decree of, 452 ; its finan- 
 cial difficulties and measures, 596 sq. 
 598 sq. 
 
 C. X. 
 
 Callias, family of, and its wealth, 482 
 
 Callias, son of Calliades, 484 
 
 Callias, the mine proprietor, 484 ; dis- 
 covered a method of making cinna- 
 bar, 629 
 
 Callistratus, the son of Callicrates, 228, 
 318, 419, 488 
 
 Campaigns, duration of, 287 
 
 Carthage, >dews of Athens against it, 
 291 
 
 Cassander, his arrangement respecting 
 the rights of citizenship, 487 
 
 Cavalry of the Athenians, 43, 274, 288; 
 pay of, 251; ratio to the infantry, 
 263; provision money of the cavalry, 
 251 
 
 Centesima {jisura), 125, 130, 534 
 
 Chalcideansreceivedshipsfrom Athens, 
 256 
 
 Chalcis, a state of cleruchi, 426 
 
 Chabrias, his profligate life, 293 
 
 Chares, his profligacy, 292 
 
 X.ecp68oTov, 128 
 
 X€Lp6ypa<pov, 128 
 
 Xeipoovd^iov, 300 
 
 XXu/xvy, 105 
 
 Choregia, 449, 454 sq. 461 sq.; of the 
 resident aliens, 537 sq. 
 
 Chorus of comedy altered, 461 
 
 Xcopiy oIkovvt€S, 261 
 
 XpvfTos and xP'^^''-^'^-> difference be- 
 tween, 23 
 
 Cimon, his liberality, 115, 486 ; his mili- 
 tary force, 259; takes Thasos, 312; 
 compare 313 ; his fines, 385 
 
 Cinnabar, 628 sq.; method of preparing 
 discovered by Callias, 629 
 
 Cistophori, 20 
 
 Citizens, number of at Athens, 32 sqq. 
 
 Citizenship, rights of fixed by Antipa- 
 ter and Cassander, 486 ; sold at By- 
 zantium, 599 
 
 Clarotge, 425, 475 
 
 Classes, three, 505 sq. 
 
 Clazomenians, iron money of the, 590 
 
 Cleomenes, satrap of Egypt, 84 
 
 Cleon, 43; his policy, 394; his pro- 
 perty, 485 
 
 Clerks, 185 
 
 Cleruchi, 424 ; Athenian citizens, 429 
 
 Cleruchiae, 115, 217, 424 sqq. 
 
 Clothing, 104 
 
 Colacretse, 173 sq. 360 
 
 Colchis, gold washings at, 8 
 
 Commercial court, 49 
 
 Commercial weights, 144 
 
 Confiscation of property, 392 ; not 
 productive, 395 
 
 Conon, his property, 22 
 
 Constantine the Great, 1 1 
 
 Contributions, 585 
 
 Copper coins of .the Athenians, 15, 29, 
 30, 592 
 
 Copper money issued by Timotheus, 
 294, 593 
 
 Copper ores at Laurion, 628 
 
 Corinthians sold triremes to the Athe- 
 nians, 109 
 
 Corn, prices of, 93 sq. 
 
 Corn, regulations with regard to, 81 sqq. 
 
 Corn, engrossing of, 82 sqq. 
 
 Corn land in Attica, 80
 
 NDEX 
 
 681 
 
 Courts of justice, 23 T i 
 
 Craterus, collector of decrees, 198 ' 
 
 Crenides, mines of, 8 
 Crossus, offerings of, 40 ; stater of, 22 
 Crowns, weight of golden, 25 ; bestowal 
 
 of them, 246, 247 
 Custom duties, 313 sqq.; farmers of, | 
 
 336 ; frauds committed by the far- ; 
 
 mers of, 316 sq.; by land, 319 ! 
 
 Cyrus the Younger, amount of pay ; 
 
 given by, 273 
 Cythera, tribute of, 401 
 Cyzicenic stater, 10, 1 1 
 Cyzicus, battle of, 269 
 
 D. A. 
 
 Damaretion, 24 
 
 Darics, 21 
 
 Aa(TfJLo\oye7v, 586 
 
 Datum, mines of, 8 ; Callistratus foun- 
 der of, 228 
 
 Debt, national, 142 
 
 Debtors, public, 385 sqq. 
 
 Deigma, 58 
 
 AcKaTT), 300, 304 sq. 
 
 AeKUTevTTjpioVj 325, 326, 336 
 
 AcKUTTjXoyia, 326, 336 
 
 AeKaTTjXoyoi, 327, 336 
 
 AeKarevTaij 327 
 
 Ae/<arcoi/at, 327, 336 
 
 Delian archons, 406 
 
 Delos, claims of the Athenians to, 410 
 
 Delphi, temple of, properly indepen- 
 dent, 602 
 
 Demades, 169, 170, 225, 3S3 
 
 Demarchs, 157, 512 sq. 
 
 Demetrias, a sacred trireme, 240 
 
 Demetrius Phalereus, census in the 
 time of, 35 ; his financial adminis- 
 tration, 440 
 
 ATjfjLioTrpara, 197, 475 sq. 392 sqq. 
 
 Atjuoctioi, 207 
 
 Demosthenes against Meidias inter- 
 preted, 374, 377 ; first oration against 
 Aristogeiton of doubtful autliority, 
 the second spurious, 34 ; the oration 
 Tzepl avvrd^eois spurious, 65 ; the 
 fourth Philippic spurious, 181, 219; 
 the speech against Timotheus spu- 
 rious, 229 ; speech against Polycles 
 explained and emended, 135 sq.; 
 against Lacritus explained, 137 sq.; 
 oration concerning the symmorise, 
 257; the npoolpLu br)p.r]yopiKay the 
 orations against Nicostratus, Pliae- 
 nippus, Nesera, T^ieocrines, Onetor, 
 Euergus and Mnesiljulus and others, 
 are falsely ascribed to Demosthenes. 
 
 Property of Demosthenes, 478, 491; 
 oration against Meidias belongs to 
 Olymp 106—4, 525, 567; or ition 
 against Boeotus de nomine about 
 Olymp. 107 — 1, 525 ; his regulation 
 of the symmorise, 564 sq.; law of the 
 trierarchy, 570 sq. 
 
 ArjjjLOTiKr] Upd, ioprai, dvcriai, 212, 213 
 
 ArjixoTiKO. Ifpd, 212 
 
 Denarius, 18 
 
 A(pp.aTLK6v, 333 
 
 AtdSo^oj in the trierarchy, 543 
 
 AiaSoVei?, 89, 216 
 
 Disetetae, pay of the, 236, 237 ; whether 
 an isoteles could be a diaetetes, 540 
 
 AiayoryLov, 300 ; of the Byzantines, 
 326 
 
 Aidypap-p-a of the sjTnmoria?, 533 ; tcov 
 
 (TK.€VaiVy 563 
 
 Aiaypa(f)rjs, 157, 533 
 
 Aiavofiaiy 216 sqq. 
 
 AtaTTuXtov, 324 
 
 AUui anb avp^oXuiVy 49, 403 
 
 AipiOipiay 274 
 
 Diobelia, 222 sqq. 
 
 AioiKTjais lepd koI oa'ia, 169 
 
 Dionysius the Brazen, 593 
 
 Dionysius the Elder, his military force, 
 255 ; coined false money, 59 1 
 
 Diophantus proposed to make the ma- 
 nual labourers public slaves, 45, 475 
 
 Diphilus, property of, 34, 169, 485 
 
 Docks in the Piraeus, 201; inspectors 
 of, 203 
 
 Aopv8p€7ravoVj 282 
 
 AovXeia of the allies, 409 
 
 AwpodoKias ypa(f)r]y 372, 384 
 
 Acopo^evuis ypa<pr], 349 
 
 Dowry, 514 sq. 
 
 Drachma, the common money of ac- 
 count, 16 sq.; heavy iEginetan, light 
 Attic, 16 ; drachma before the time 
 of Solon, 16, 144 sqq. 
 
 Duties, high out of Attica, 334 
 
 E. 
 
 Economy, divided by Aristotle into 
 
 four kinds, 299 
 Eels, Copaic, 103 
 
 ElKoarrj, 325, 401 
 EtKocrroXoyoi, 325, 336 
 EiVayyeXta, 55, 357, 380 
 ElacjiepeiPj 539 
 Ela-cpopd, object of, 181, 470 
 "EkSoo-is, 132 
 ^EKXeyeiv to reXos, 335 
 'ExXoy^y, 156, 177, 335
 
 682 
 
 XDEX. 
 
 'EK(f)6piov, 300 
 Eleusis, a fortress, 202 
 'EXev^epi'a of the allies, 409 
 'EXXi/xeVtoi/, 320 
 ' EXKifieviarai, 320, 336 
 Embassadors, pay of, 237 sqq. 
 Emeralds, 628 
 "EfjL^Tjvoi dUai, 50, 667 
 'EixTTopiov, taxes from, 313 
 "EfinopoL, 313 
 
 "Er8fi|iy, 373, 388, 389, 392 
 ^Eyyeypap-fievos iv ^AKponoXei, 388 
 'Eyypacprj Qeap-oBeTcdv, 388 
 Engrossing restrained in Attica, 82 
 "EyyvoL, eyyvrjrai, 335 
 'Ey KTTjTiKov, 297 
 'Evi/o/itov, 468 • 
 'Ei/oiKi'ov btKT], 354 
 'EiTos-, 668 
 "Ecpea-eLs, 360 
 'E7ri/3arat, 279 
 Epicrates, property of, 485 
 Epidemeticum, 285 
 'ETTiSoo-iy, 567, 586 
 'ETnyva>p.ov(S, 305 
 'E7Tiypa(p?is, 156, 157, 533 
 'EnLKapTria, 300 
 'E7riKe(^dXatoi/, 300 
 ^EttlkXtjpoi, 357 sq. 
 ^ETTifxax'to., 403 
 'ETnixeXrjTrjS ttjs KOiprjs Trpoa-odov^ 164 ; 
 
 entpe'krjTa). tov epnopiov, 48, 81 ; 
 
 eTnp-eXTjTai Ta>v Aiovvaicov, 215; of 
 
 the sacred olive trees, 305 
 ^ETnarjixaiveaduL ras evBvvas, 193 
 'ETTtcTKOTrot, 156, 238 
 'ETTio-rarai of the temples, 161; rav 
 
 brjpLOCTioiv €py(ov, vbdrcov, 203 
 'ETTi'^erot eoprai, 211 
 'ETnTpiTjpdpxrjp-a, 543 
 'E7rtrpo7r>)s Sikt;, 353 sq. 
 Epobelia, 132, 364 sq. 
 'Ettcoi/iov, 323 
 
 Equestrian nations of Greece, 258 
 "Bpavos, 245 
 'Epe'rai, 280 
 ^EpyaarTTjptov, 655 
 'Y.pyo\dfioi, 204 
 'E(r;(ariai, 63 
 Euboea imder the Athenian dominion, 
 
 411, 427 
 Eubcean wars, 549, 567 
 Eiibulus of Anaphlystus, 150, 180, 225 
 Euripides the Yoxmger, tax proposed 
 
 by, 493, 506, 520 
 EvOvva, 196 
 EvBvvoi, 189 sq. 
 'E^aipeVecas 8ikt;, .378 
 Exchange, 514, 580 sqq. 674 
 'E^€Ta<TTaiy 292 
 
 'E^ovXtjs biKt], 317 sqq. 669 sqq. 
 Exports from Attica, 41, 47 
 
 Fifth, 323 
 
 Fiftieth, produce of, 318 ; of the gods 
 and heroes of the tribes, 329 
 
 Financial difficulties of states, 584 
 sqq. 
 
 Fines, 375, 382 ; under what condi- 
 tions they could be remitted, 391, 
 392 ; low rate in the laws of Solon, 
 375 
 
 Fish, prices of, 102, 103 
 
 Fishmongers, 103 
 
 Foreign dancers, 377 
 
 Fortifications of Athens and other 
 places in Attica, 201 sq. 
 
 Fortune-tellers, tax on, at Byzantium, 
 332 
 
 Freedmen, protection money, and 
 triobolon of, 330, 332 
 
 G. r. 
 
 Galepsus, 312 
 
 Generals, different kinds of, 181 ; their 
 
 lavish expenditure, 292, sq. 
 Tepa, 495 
 Teaxpdviov, 631 
 r^ dpyvplris^ 624 
 Gold, rare in the earliest times, 7, 21; 
 
 ratio of to silver, 21, 27 ; coins of in 
 
 Greece, 21 sq. ; issued by Athens, 
 
 21, 592; bad gold coins, 592 ; gold 
 
 talent, 24 sq. 
 Tpap,fjLaT€vs, 185 ; different kinds of, 
 
 186 sqq. 
 Tpacfyai, 349 
 Guardians, actions for misconduct of, 
 
 353 
 Gyges, his sacred offerings, 10 
 Gymnasiarchy, 401 sqq. 
 
 H. 
 
 Hadrian, law of, respecting the fur- 
 nishing of oil, 305 
 
 Halmyris, 468 
 
 Harpalus, 12 
 
 Harpocration emended, 512 
 
 Hecatombs, 75 
 
 Hegemon of Thasos, his lawsuit, 405 
 
 Hegemonia of Athens, duration of it, 
 444 
 
 Helena, island of, its area, 3 1
 
 XDEX. 
 
 683 
 
 Hellenotamige, 167, 176 sq. 402 
 
 Helots, 258, 2G1, 475 
 
 'Eo-Tiao-is, 452, 465 ; of the resident 
 
 aliens, 538 
 'Eraiprjo-ecos ypa(f)rf, 380 
 'ErepoTrXovy, 57, 133 
 'ifpoSovXoi, 70 
 Hieron of Syracuse, 7 
 'lepoTToioiy 216 
 
 Hierum on the Bosporus, 137 
 'iTTTraycoya liKoia, 288 
 'iTTTr^s-, LTTTrdba reXovvres, 495; see 
 
 Knights. 
 Hippias the Pisistratid, his financial 
 measures, 592 ; sold the parts of the 
 houses which projected into the 
 street, 64, 598 ; sold an exemption 
 from the liturgies, 598 
 Hippodamus built the Piraeus, 64 
 ^ImroKOfjLos, 271 
 Hipponicus, his family and wealth, 
 
 481, 482 
 'OdoTTOLoi, 203 
 Honey, price of, 104 ; of the mines, 
 
 632 
 Hopletes, tribe at Athens, 494 
 Hoplitse, number of, 260, 266 sq. ; 
 pei-sons who served as hoplitae, 500 ; 
 resident aliens as hoplitae, 260 sq. 
 'OTrXiraycoyoL Tpirjpeis, 279 
 "Opoi on mortgaged lands, 129, 512 
 Horses, price of, in Attica, 73, 74, 
 
 490 
 Houses let by the state and by the 
 temples, 305 ; their value in Attica, 
 66 sq. ; their number, 39, 64 ; me- 
 thod of building at Athens, 64 
 Houses, rent of, 140 sqq. 
 Himdreth, duty of, 321 
 "Y^peccs dUr} or ypa(f)^, 364, 374, 380, 
 
 387 
 Hydriaphoria, 538 
 YXcopoi, 303 
 
 YTTrjKooi., subject allies, 403 
 YTTTjpeo-La opposed to dpxrjy 239 
 YTTTjpeTai, sailors, 280 
 YTTTjperqs of the hoplitae, 271 
 YTroypajJLfiaTevs, 187 
 YnoTeXels, 408 
 YTroTinrjo-iSj 510 
 
 I. 
 
 Imports of Attica, 47 
 
 Incomes of the citizens, as compared 
 
 with the taxes, 460 
 Independent allies of Athens, 403 
 Independent and tributary allies, 407 
 India, gold of, 9 
 
 Industry, taxes on, 332 
 Inheritance of public debts, 391 
 Intercourse with men and women, 
 
 price of, fixed by the state, 122, 
 
 333 
 Ionia, large revenues accruing to the 
 
 Athenians from, 412 
 Iron money, 590, 595, 596 
 Isaeus emended, 477 
 Ischomachus, his property, 479 
 Islands, subject to tlie Athenians, 411 
 Isoteles, could possess landed property 
 
 in Attica, 540; their rights, &c., 
 
 539 sq. 654 
 
 J. 
 
 Jurisdiction of Athens over the allies, 
 403 sqq. 
 
 K. 
 
 KaivoTOfji€7v, 635 
 
 Kara^okr] re'Xovs", 338 
 
 Keyxpeayv, 638 sq. 
 
 K€yxpo9, 638 sq. 
 
 Knights, order of, at Athens, 263 sq. 
 
 495 sq. ; theii" right to fill superior 
 
 offices, 507 ; see Imrrjs. 
 KoivcoviKdj 545 sq. 
 
 Lachares, the tyrant, 597 
 
 Laconia, estates in, 81 
 
 Lampadarchy, 463 
 
 Land, value of, 62 sq. ; division of in 
 Attica, 486 
 
 Land forces of Athens, 254 sqq. 
 
 Land tax, not regular at Athens, 297 
 
 Laurion, mines of, 409, 615 ; their im- 
 portance to Athens, 616 ; situation 
 of, 616 sq. ; defended by fortresses, 
 620 sq. ; metals found in, 624 sq. ; 
 right of property in, 645 ; belonged 
 to the state, 645; were let in perpe- 
 tuity, 645 ; Xenophon's proposals 
 with regard to, 606 
 
 Lauriotis, 641 
 
 Lead, price of, 30 ; found in the mines 
 of Laurion, 625, 627 
 
 Lease, advertisement of, by the 
 demus Piraeus, 307, 467 
 
 Leather money, 596 
 
 AenroixapTvplov dUrj, 371 
 
 Letting of public property, 303 
 
 Leucon, comedy of, the "Ovos dcrK0(f)6- 
 pos, 324
 
 684 
 
 NDEX. 
 
 Lexicon Segiueraniim emended, 313, 
 316 
 
 Litras, 17 
 
 Liturgies, 448 sqq. ; superintendence 
 of, 157 ; as revenues of the state, 
 448 ; liturgies in other Grecian 
 states besides Athens, 298 ; Xeirovp- 
 yiai ficTOLKOiv and noXiTiKal, 637 sq.; 
 liturgi, 526 
 
 Loans, 587 
 
 Aoxos, 278 
 
 Aoyio-nos, 190 sq. 
 
 Aoyiarai, 1 89 sqq= ; were open to 
 bribery, 195 
 
 liupins, 103 
 
 Lycurgus, 1C5, 167, 169, 218; his 
 accounts, 196 ; completed the docks, 
 20) ; liis financial administration, 
 436 sqq. 
 
 Lysander sent large sums of money to 
 Sparta, 29 
 
 M. 
 
 Manager of the public revenue, 1 64 sqq. 
 
 Marathon, battle of, 257 ; festival for 
 it, 212 
 
 Maroneia, 619 
 
 Mdarpoi and /JLaarrjpes, 158 
 
 MdCa, 96 
 
 Meals of the Athenians, 191 
 
 Medifxvos o-LTTjpoSy size of, 91 
 
 Mr}vvTpa, 248 
 
 ISIercenaries, 291 
 
 Metals, the precious, places where 
 they were found in Greece, 7 sqq. ; 
 the use of forbidden to private indi- 
 
 ■ viduals in Sparta, 594 ; species of 
 metals found in the Laui'ion mines, 
 624 sq. 
 
 MeraXXiKos vopos, 
 
 Aletronomi, 48 
 
 Metroum, 405 
 
 Mines of Laurion, 43 ; manner in 
 which they were let, 73, 142, 155, 
 310, 645 ; revenues from them, 649 
 sq. ; value of a single share, 655 ; 
 see Laurion. 
 
 Mint at Athens, 144, 642 
 
 Miados, pay of the soldiers, 272 ; 
 meaning of the word picrOoi in the 
 Wasps of Aristophanes, 298 ; piaBol 
 Tpi.-qpapx'-as,b']{); piaOos ^ovXcvtikos, 
 232 sq. ; SiKao-ri/cos, 232 sq. ; ckkXtj- 
 (TiaaTiKos, 228 sq. ; avvqyopiKos, 233 
 
 MicjQoicns oiKOVj 142 ; blio} fj.La66icre<os 
 o'Uov, 355 sq. 
 
 Miadovpevoi, tenants of landed estates, 
 335 ; used by the grammarians for 
 perpetual tenants, 651 
 
 Missiles, 289 
 
 Mixture of languages at Athens, 47 
 
 Moixeias ypa(PT], 349 
 
 Money, exportation of, 46 
 
 Monopolies of the state, 52 sq. 698. 
 
 Myronides, 228 
 
 Mytilene, cleruchi there, 430 ; rent or 
 
 tribute paid by the Mytileneans to 
 
 them, 431, 602 
 
 N. 
 
 National wealth of Attica, 487 ; how 
 
 distributed, 486 
 NavKXrjpiKci, 178 
 'NavKXrjpoi, speculators in houses, 141, 
 
 306 
 Naucrari, 157, 512, 548 ; origin of the 
 
 name, 548 ; TTpvTaveLS tcov vavKpdpmv, 
 
 255 
 Naucrarias of Solon and of Cleisthenes, 
 
 255 sq. 548 sq. 
 Navcriv vtttjkooi, 408 
 Nausinicus, valuation in the archon- 
 
 ship of, 615 sqq. 520, 523, 539 
 Nairai, 280 
 
 NavTLKov, bottomry, 606 
 Nautodicse, 49 
 
 Naval force of Athens, 255 sq. 265 sq. 
 Naxos, subjection of, 409 
 Nicias, the son of Niceratus, his family 
 
 and its wealth, 480 ; his expedition 
 
 to Sicily, 266 j his archetheoria, 
 
 214 
 'Nopiapa imx^pt-ov, 29; Koivbv 'EXXt;- 
 
 viKov, 593 
 Nd/ioi reXcofiKot, 337 
 Nopa)VT]Sy 304 
 Nomothetse, 239 
 Nummus of the Sicilians, 17 
 
 O. Q. 
 
 Obligation to military service accord- 
 ing to the different classes, 500 
 
 Obolus and obelus, 97 ; o/3eXot and 
 o^eXiaKoi, spits, 594 
 
 Oenoe, a fortress, 202 
 
 OIkos, the whole property, different 
 from oiKia, 110, 142, 354 
 
 Oil, price of, 99 
 
 Olives, 1 04 ; culture of encouraged, 4 1 
 
 Olive trees, action for destroying them, 
 41,352 
 
 OlvovTTa, 287 
 
 Ointment, price of, 106 
 
 Olynthian wars, 569 
 
 ^QveicrSai used of the public revenue, 
 110,335
 
 INDEX. 
 
 685 
 
 Opisthodomus of Minerva, treasure 
 
 preserved there, 441 
 "Oyjrov, 101 
 'OpyecovLKo. lepd, 212 
 "Opo^oi, 103 
 Oropus, custom duties taken there, 
 
 319 
 "Oa-TpaKiafxos, 231, 393 
 Ovaia (fiavepa and d(f)avr]S, 489 
 Oxen, prices of, CI, 75 
 
 P. n. $. *. 
 
 TLapd^oXov, 360 
 
 TJapaKaTa^oXt], 3C0 
 
 TLdpaXoi, TrapaXiraiy 240 ; all freemen, 
 
 262 
 UdpaKos, treasurer of the, 171 
 TLapavoixcou ypa(f)T], 280, 282 
 IlapaTrpecr^eias ypa(f)r}, 283 
 Udpedpoi of the hellenotamiae, 180 ; 
 
 of the euthuni, 191 
 Parthenon, treasure preserved there, 
 
 442 
 Pasion the banker, 480, 486, 537, 586 
 Passports, 207 
 HdrpioL 3vai.aij 211 
 narpKOTiKd at Byzantium confiscated, 
 
 598 
 Peloponnesian war, expenses of, 290 
 Penestae, 261, 475, 494 
 Pentacosiomedimni, 495 sqq. ; when 
 
 they served in war, 262, 500, 501 
 UevTrjKoa-rrj, 314; tov (tItov, 315 
 Pericles, 11, 195 sqq. 232, 597 ; his 
 administration of the tributes, 399, 
 400 ; cleruchise sent out at his re- 
 commendation, 427 
 Persians, provisioned their troops from 
 the enemy's country, 285 ; gave sub- 
 sidies to the Greeks, particularly to 
 the Spartans, 11, 584; revenues and 
 treasure of Persia, 9 ; Pei-sian booty 
 enriched the Greeks, 11, 585 
 Persons, taxes on, 297 
 Phasis, 85, 368, 386, 66.S 
 Phidias, 195 
 
 Phidon did not coin gold, 20; sup- 
 planted the use of obeli or spits, 594 
 Philippi, mines there, 8 
 Philochorus, a collector of inscriptions, 
 
 197 ; his date, 244 
 Phocaic stater, 22, 23 
 Phoceans, coined gold from the trea- 
 sures at Delphi, 1 1 ; their claims to 
 the temple of Delphi, 601, 602 
 Phocion, 12 ; his expeditions into Eu- 
 
 boea, 569 
 ^opfjLoif 82 
 
 ^opoi, 396, 397, 419 
 ^aypcov }<ipT)v, 337 
 ^liXaKes, 156 
 Phyle, a fortress, 202 
 Physicians, pay of, 120 
 Pisistratus, originator of the mainte- 
 nance for the poor, 242 
 
 Plataefe, battle of, 257 
 
 Platsean rights of citizenship at Athens, 
 262 
 
 Pledge, 128 
 
 UXrjpoifia, 278, 279 
 
 Plethron, size of, 62 
 
 Plumarius, 69 
 
 Plunder in war, 585 
 
 Plutarch of Eretria, 569 
 
 UoikiXtcu, 69 
 
 Polemon, 6 o-rr^XoKOTras, 197 
 
 Poletse, 155, 646 
 
 TIcoXijT-qpiov TOV p,eTOiKLOv, 330 
 
 Political economy, knowledge of 
 among the Greeks, 3 
 
 Poll-tax, 301, 302 
 
 Pollux explained, 499 
 
 Polybius refuted, 487 sqq. 
 
 Population of Attica, 30 sqq. 
 
 Uopia-Toij 166 
 
 IlopviKov reXos, 333 
 
 IlopvoTeXayvai, 333 
 
 Potidaea, tax there, 534 
 
 Poverty great at Athens in later 
 times, 486, 487 
 
 npdicTopes, 156, 376 
 
 Ilpidfjifvoi, used of custom-duties, 335 
 
 Privateer, licences to, 585 
 
 npo/3oXj7, 374, 665 
 
 Ilpodocrias ypacp-q, 384 
 
 Upo€i(T(popd, 299, 450, 526, 533 
 
 Profits of the merchants, 58, 59 
 
 npo/cara/3oXi7, 342 
 
 Prometretae, 48, 239 
 
 Property, immoveable, 489 ; move- 
 able, 489 ; necessary for the com- 
 plete rights of citizenship, 487 ; re- 
 gisters of property, 510 sqq. 
 
 Property of the temples of Delphi 
 and Delos lent out at interest, 308, 
 589 
 
 Property tax, when first levied at 
 Athens, 471 
 
 Property taxes, 492, 505, 515,623; not 
 a liturgy, 472 
 
 Propylaea, the expense of, 202, 444 
 
 npoaKard^XtjiJia, 342 
 
 Upoa-TifiTjfia, 373, 380,382, 390 
 
 Upo^evoi, 50, 140, 238, 513, 540 
 
 Provision money, 272, 275, 282 
 
 Provisioning of armies, 282 sqq. 
 
 Prytaneas, payment according to them, 
 141, 241, 243, 306, 338; in later
 
 686 
 
 XDEX. 
 
 times coincided with the months, 
 241, 244 
 
 Prytaneia, justice-fees, 345 sqq. 
 
 Prytanes, originally judges, 173 
 
 Prytaneum, maintenance there, 246 
 
 "irevBeyypacprjS ypacprj, 349, 390 
 
 SirevboKkfjaias, "^evdoKXrjTelas ypa(t)r], 
 349, 382, 390 
 
 "^evbop-apTvpiov biicr), 373 
 
 ^iXoi, 500 
 
 ^v;(a'yco'yia, 635 
 
 Ptolemais, sacred trireme, 240 
 
 Ptolemies, their wealth, 13 
 
 Public assembly, numbei-s of, 230 sq. 
 
 Public property, 302, 512; sold at 
 Byzantium, 598 
 
 Purple, price of, 105 
 
 Pythes, or Pythius, prince of Celsense, 
 9 
 
 Pythocles proposed to the state to ob- 
 tain a monopoly of lead, 30, 52, 627 
 
 Quartering, not admissible in Greece, 
 284 
 
 R. 
 
 Ransom, 71, 72 
 
 Registers of property, 510 sqq. 
 
 Rent of land in Attica, 141, 142 
 
 Reprisals, 585 
 
 Requisitions, 284 
 
 Resident aliens, number of, in Attica, 
 
 35 sq.; indispensable for Athens, 44; 
 
 served in war, 260, 261, 265, 268; 
 
 had not the right of possessing 
 
 landed property, 140 ; their services, 
 
 537 sq. ; their immunities, 537, 538 
 Responsibility of public officers, 189 
 Revenue of Athens, 433 sqq. 
 Rhamnus, a fortress, 202 
 Rhodian laws, 133 
 Roads, construction of, 202 
 Roman pound, 18 
 Rowers, of three kinds, 281; divided 
 
 into six lochi, 278 ; their arms, 281, 
 
 282 
 
 S. 2. 
 
 2aKxi^<^"VTat, 69 
 
 2aXa|, 636 
 
 Salaminia, 240 ; its crew called Sala- 
 
 minians, 240 
 Salamis, area of, 31 ; battle of, 208, 
 
 250 
 Sales, tax on, 323 
 
 Salt in Attica, 100 
 
 Samos, when settled by cleruchi, 428 
 
 Samothrace, tribute of, 414 
 
 Scaphephoria, 538 
 
 Scapte Hyle, 7,313 
 
 Sciadephoria, 538 
 
 Scythians, 208 
 
 ^eiaaxdeia of Solon, 16, 126, 129, 145, 
 
 482, 495 
 Self- valuation, 510 
 Senate of Five Hundred, its financial 
 
 powers, 153 
 Seuthes, rate of pay given by, 274 
 Sheep, prices of, 76 
 Shipbuilding, 107, 108, 554 sqq. 
 Ships' furniture, price of, 108 
 Sicilian war, 2G6 sqq. 290 sq. 
 Sieges, expenses of, 289, 290 
 Sil, 630 
 Silver found in the mines of Laurion, 
 
 624 
 Silver money of the Athenians, 14 
 Silver ornaments, 491 
 ^iTrjpeaiov, aiTapKeia, alros, 272 
 ^LToboaiai, 89 
 Sitonse, 88 
 Sitophylaces, 83 
 '2Kevo(f)6pos, 271 
 ^Kopobov iv diKTvois, 286 
 ^KvpcoTTj odos, 203 
 Slaves, their number in Attica, 35, 36 ; 
 
 of Mnason, 117; their employments, 
 
 37; served in war, 257, 26"'l, 262; 
 
 at Corinth and yEgina, 38; worked 
 
 as day-labourers, 37, 72 ; prices of, 
 
 67 sqq. ; profit obtained on them, 72, 
 
 659 ; duty on, 331 
 Socrates, his property, mode and 
 
 means of li^"ing, 109 sq. 
 Solon, his institution of classes, and 
 
 changes in the government, 495 sqq. 
 
 506 sq.; his alteration of the money 
 
 standard, 145 sq. 
 Sophists, pay of, 121 sq. 
 '2(o(f)poviaTaL, 238 
 Spain, mines of 14 
 Sparta, swallowed up much precious 
 
 metal, 29 ; its military force, 254, 258 
 Spartocus, king in the Pontus, 90 
 Speusinians, 208 
 2(f)payiSy passport, 207 
 Spuma Argenti, 637 sq. 
 Statei-s, tetradrachms, 15; Corinthian, 
 
 16; golden, 21 sq. ; Cyzicenic, 22; 
 
 gilt staters of Polycrates, 21 
 ^radnovxoi, do, 306 
 Standing armies not fitted for the 
 
 Greeks, 283 
 Si-^Xat on mortgaged lands, 129, 512 
 Stephanephorus, a hero at Athens, 144
 
 INDEX. 
 
 687 
 
 Stone, writing on, expense of, 118 
 
 Stone quames, 43, 311 
 
 Storehouse, 201, 249 
 
 "STpariaiTides rpcrjpeis, 279 
 
 Subsidies, Pei'sian, 1 1, 584 
 
 Subsistence, what sum requisite for, 
 109 sqq. 
 
 Suidas emended, 497 
 
 SCXat, avXa, 138, 585 
 
 2vXXoyi7, avWoyels, public officers, 
 158, 215 
 
 2vfi^o\ov, a passport, 207; of the di- 
 casts, 235; fit/cat dno avix^oXiovj 49, 
 403 
 
 ^vfifiaxia, 403 
 
 ^vfJLfiopLai, of the property taxes, 515 
 sq. ; 523 sq.; of the trierarchy, 559 
 sqq. ; eTnfjLeXrjToi tcov avppopLa>v, 533, 
 562 ; Tjy€p.6ves tcov crvp.iJLopLoi)v, 494, 
 532, 562 ; of the resident aliens, 538 
 
 ^vfip.np[apxoi, 532 
 
 ^vyx^ipw''^) on the part of the plain- 
 tiff, 372, 382 
 
 2vvdiKoi, 178 
 
 2vv€dpiov of the Athenian allies, 418 
 
 2vj/j)yopot, 193, 237 
 
 ^vyypa(pT], 128; vavriKJ], 133 
 
 Sunivun, a fortress, 202, 658 
 
 "SiVvoiKiaiy 65, 141 
 
 ^vurd^eis, 419, 423 
 
 Suj/reXeTy, allies who paid their tribute 
 jointly, 414 ; in the symmorise of the 
 trierarchy, 560, 561 
 
 Sureties, 49 
 
 Suttlers, 285 
 
 Syntelias, 560 sq. 
 
 Syntrierarchy, 548 sqq. 
 
 T. e. 
 
 Taxe'iai rpiTjpeis, 279 
 
 Talent, divisions and value of, 15; 
 Attic talent before the time of Solon, 
 16, 145; ^Eginetan, 16; Egj-ptian, 
 Alexandrian, 18 ; Babylonian, 19 ; 
 Euboic, 19 ; S}Tacusan or Sicilian, 
 17 ; Ptolemaic, 18 ; of Thyatira, 25 ; 
 talent of gold, 25 ; commercial 
 talent, 30, 144, 145 
 
 Tap.Las TTjs Koivrjs Trpoaodov, 164, 165 ; 
 r^y dioiKTjcrecos, 168 ; tcov TpiTjponoicov, 
 171 ; Tafxiai TCOV reip^oTTOicoi/, 171; 
 Tap,l.as Tov drjpov, 172 ; (XTpaTioiTtKcov, 
 180. See Treasurer. 
 
 Tamynae, battle of, 525 
 
 Tdpixos, 103 
 
 Taxable capital, 492, 503 
 
 Taxes, advance of, 533 sqq. 
 
 Taxes before the time of Solon, 494 ; 
 taxes of the classes, 495 sqq. ; extra- 
 ordinary, 501 sq.; of the resident 
 aliens, 541 ; on persons and on the 
 soil only imposed by tyrants, 301 
 
 Taxes, register of, 510 sqq. 
 
 TetxoTTOioi, 170, 203 
 
 TeXeoi/res-, 494 
 
 TeXcovai, 155, 335 
 
 TfXcoviKoi vopioi, 337 
 
 TeXcovdpxrjS, 336 
 
 Te'Xoy, 297, 302, 471; reXoy rcXeTj/, 50 1 ; 
 reXr/. 297, 298 ; reXj? of Solon, 495 
 
 T€p.evos, object of, 303 
 
 Terp(i)/3oXov ^ios, 273 
 
 Thasos, mines of, 7 ; produce of them, 
 311 
 
 Theatre, cost of, 210, 213; entrance- 
 money to, 219 sqq. 
 
 QeaTpa>in]s, OeaTponcoXrjs, 220 
 
 Themistocles, his law with respect to 
 the building of ships, 249, 652 sqq. ; 
 his courtezans, 292 ; his property, 485 
 
 Theopompus, 225, 293 
 
 Theori, 214 sq. 
 
 Theoria, Delian, 214 
 
 Theoricon, managers of, 170 sq.; gene- 
 ral account of it, 216 sqq.; its rela- 
 tion to the funds for war, 170, 181 ; 
 distribution of, 219 sq. 
 
 QeppoVf 104 
 
 Thetes, yj/iXol, 500 ; made hoplitse, 257, 
 500 ; served in the ships, 262, 500 ; 
 original meaning of the word, 494 ; 
 meaning after the time of Solon, 496 
 
 QLaercoTiKa in Byzantium confiscated, 
 598 
 
 Thoricus, a fortress, 202 ; its situation, 
 618; the modern Therico, 618 
 
 Thousand drachmas, fine of, 379 
 
 Thracian mines, 312 
 
 Thrasyllus, 619 
 
 Thucydides the historian, his mines in 
 Thrace, 312 
 
 Thucydides, decree of for the ^Enians, 
 420 
 
 Qveiv dno picrdoopdTcov, 211 
 
 Timber for shipbuilding, want of, in 
 Attica, 250 
 
 Tip^fiaTa, 298, 345, 362, 367, 370 sqq.; 
 of Solon, 495, 503 ; meaning of the 
 word Tipi]p,a as connected with 
 taxes, 503 
 
 Tip.r]pa, taxable capital, 492 
 
 Timocrates, his law respecting the 
 public debtors, 339 sq. 
 
 Timotheus, the son of Conon, 293 sq.; 
 415 sq. 
 
 Tissaphemes, what rate of pav given 
 by, 276
 
 688 
 
 NDEX. 
 
 Tithes, different kinds of, 326, 327 sq.; 
 to the goddess, 160, 328 
 
 Tithes of the Athenians at Byzantium, 
 325, 415 
 
 ToKoyXvCpos, 127 
 
 Tokos tyyeios, eyyvos, 129; vavTKos, 
 132 
 
 To^apxos, 208 
 
 To^drat, 208; To^orm ^eviKol, dariKol, 
 2'J5; see Bowmen. 
 
 Trade, freedom of, 51 sqq. 
 
 Trading vessels, 48 
 
 Tpta/caSey, 32 
 
 Treasiu-e, public, of Athens, 10, 160 
 sq. ; 441 sqq. 
 
 Treasurers of the tribes and boroughs, 
 160; of the sacred monies, 160, 168, 
 196; treasurer of the administra- 
 tion, 168; of the generals, 181 ; of 
 the triremes and trierarchs, 182; 
 see Ta/xi'ay. 
 
 TpiaKoaiofxedifjLvoi, 497 
 
 Tributes of the allies, 298, 396 sqq.; of 
 the states of cleruchi, 432 
 
 Tributary states of Athens, 409 sqq. 
 
 Tiierarchy, 541 sqq.; 547, 578; ex- 
 penses of it, 577; trierarchy for 
 mock sea-fights, 452 ; frauds of the 
 trierarchs, 292 
 
 Tpirjpapxos, not Tptr]pdp)(T]s, the ancient 
 form, 571 
 
 Tpip.oipia, 274 
 
 Tpico^oXoi/, 229, 234, 605; slave duty, 
 331 
 
 Triremes, kinds of, 279 ; sacred, I7I, 
 240 ; number of the Attic, 259 sqq.; 
 265 sq. ; nimibers of the crews, 280 
 
 Trumpeters, 9 1 
 
 Twentieth, imposed by the Pisistra- 
 tidae, 327 ; in the allied states, 325 
 
 U. 
 
 Ulpian, scholiast of Demosthenes, 450, 
 526, 527, 651 
 
 Valuation in the archonship of Nau- 
 
 sinicus, 487, 493 sqq. 
 Vectigal prcBiorium, 285 
 
 W. 
 
 Wages of labour, 116 sqq. 
 
 Weights and measures at Athens, 49, 
 
 144 
 Wine, cheapness of, 98 
 Wood in Attica, 100 
 
 Sevias ypa(j)r}, 90, 349 
 
 SevLKo. reXeTr, 332 
 
 Xenophou nepl rropcov, 4, 37, 136, 600 
 
 sq. ; date of its composition, 600 sq.; 
 
 on the authenticity of his Essay on 
 
 the Athenian state, 44, 321; Qi^co- 
 
 nomics explained, 579 
 
 Z^TTjTaly 158 
 Z^vyiaiov, 496 
 Z?vy irai, 496 
 Zfvyoy, 496 
 Zvyirat, 281 
 
 London:— Harrison anu Co., i'niNTKKS, St. Martto's Lank.
 
 
 U^ ^'; ^^a>'2ij> ^'>-^ 
 
 
 S>X> ^' :2I>. :>> :D.L> '^ ^^ 
 
 » 
 
 > >) ■>. i:;^^ i^ >>o ^ > >:> 
 
 ^ :i^ >. 
 
 l''^ (:/.^^-f>;S^ ^jo 
 
 -0> > 
 
 
 
 ESHIpo^Z^^^^ ?5^^ 'i> 3\. 
 
 > ^:) 
 
 f^S-iff^ji _i3*>II!!>L»' Ol> 'j[> >> ^) 
 
 -^'L-^ 
 ^~>> 
 
 " ^>:^''^:>-> ^^)y^>o 
 
 
 ■ ^'L^t^^_ jL:P^J>j!y,j 
 
 
 > > » 
 
 <5niiTucni'«X®'^"y <>' California 
 4of ^Vll^rn'^'^ REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 
 405 H-lgard Avenue, Los Angeles. CA 90024-1388 
 Return this material to the library 
 trom which it was borrnwoH 
 
 
 : 2Qoe 
 
 ^002 
 
 
 
 ^^■ 
 
 
 '-^ _^8> : 
 
 ^ > 
 
 
 > IS 
 
 .j^' o"^
 
 
 DJ)Z^ 
 
 ^3) 
 
 u 
 
 ?>^ — 
 
 
 
 
 
 J) >> 
 
 
 
 A 000 177 832 
 
 
 
 
 ^^ - ;^ 
 
 
 p 
 
 >L:^i>^ 
 
 ^1 

 
 ^^mmMmmm^mmwiimmmmi