THE LIBRARY 
 
 OF 
 
 THE UNIVERSITY 
 
 OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 LOS ANGELES 
 
V 
 
 c~~y\ -^/V 
 
 I V 
 
THE 
 
 EGYPTIAN LAW 
 
 OF 
 
 OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 A COMPARATIVE STUDY WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE 
 . . TO THE FRENCH AND THE ENGLISH LAW. . . 
 
 BY 
 
 FREDERICK PARKER WALTON, 
 
 ADVOCATE OF THE SCOTTISH BAR, K.C. (QUEBEC), B.A. (OXON.), LL.B. (EDEN.), 
 LL.D. (ABERDEEN AND MCGILL) ; HON. MEMBER AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION ; 
 DIRECTOR OF THE SULTANIA SCHOOL OF LAW, CAIRO; FORMERLY DEAN OF 
 THE LAW FACULTY, MCGILL UNIVERSITY, MONTREAL. 
 
 AUTHOR OF 
 
 " Handbook of Husband and Wife according to the Law of Scotland " ; 
 "Scotch Marriages, Eegular and Irregular"; "Historical Introduction to 
 the Roman Law" ; " Scope and Interpretation of the Civil Code of Lower 
 Canada" ; " Workmen's Compensation Act, 1909, of the Province of Quebec, 
 with a Commentary," &c. 
 
 IN TWO VOLUMES. 
 
 Vol. II. 
 
 LONDON : 
 
 STEVENS AND SONS, LIMITED, 
 119 & 120, CHANCERY LANE, 
 
 f ato Publishers. 
 
 1920 
 
( in ) 
 
 //? 
 
 TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 VOLUME II. 
 
 OHAPTBE I. 
 
 TAGE 
 EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS 1 — 47 
 
 Confusion in the French Code between effects of contracts and 
 
 effects of obligations 1 
 
 Effects of contracts as between the parties 2 
 
 Contracts make the law between the parties 2 
 
 Modification of charitable foundations 3 
 
 Contract changes legal situation of parties 3 
 
 Interpretation of contract is question of fact 4 
 
 Exceptio non adimpleti contractus 4 
 
 Modification of contract by parties 5 
 
 Effect of modification or cancellation of contract as between the 
 
 parties 7 
 
 Effect of modification or cancellation as regards third parties ... 7 
 
 Renewal of contract 8 
 
 Exceptions to rule that contracts can be modified or revoked 
 
 by parties 9 
 
 Certain contracts can be revoked by one party or one party may 
 
 be released owing to change of circumstances 9 
 
 Effect of' contracts as between the parties and as against third 
 
 parties 11 
 
 Who are the parties to a contract? 13 
 
 Representation in contract 13 
 
 When is an agent a party ? 13 
 
 Factors and brokers 14 
 
 Involuntary representation 15 
 
 Summary 16 
 
 Heirs and successors 16 
 
 Meaning of Ayants cause 17 
 
 Universal and particular Ayants cause 18 
 
 Rule that obligations transmit to universal successors only 18 
 
 Particular representatives 19 
 
 Analogous rule in English law 23 
 
 Leases 23 
 
 Creditors 23 
 
 a 2 
 
iv TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER I — continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Summary 
 
 Exceptions to the rule that contracts do not benefit or prejudice 
 
 third parties -° 
 
 Protection given to third parties -' 
 
 Rule does not mean that contract may not be proved by third 
 
 parties as a fact 29 
 
 Translatory and non-translatory contracts 30 
 
 Effect of contracts in transferring property between the parties... 30 
 
 Roman law and old French law as to effect of contract to transfer. 32 
 
 Modern Erench law 33 
 
 Two conditions of rule 34 
 
 Rule that property passes at once is not law of public order 35 
 
 Effect of contracts in transferring property as regards third 
 
 par ties "' 
 
 Exceptions to the rule that the real right first registered is 
 
 preferred 39 
 
 Effect of alienation of corporeal moveables as against third parties. 43 
 
 Incorporeal moveables .* 4b 
 
 The effect of non-translatory contracts with regard to third 
 
 parties 4b 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 CONTRACT OF PORTE-FORT 48 — 52 
 
 Distinction between contract of porte-fort and suretyship 50 
 
 Porte- fort promises on his own account 50 
 
 If the contract is ambiguous is there a presumption that a party 
 
 binds himself as a porte-fort? 50 
 
 The ratification and its effect 51 
 
 Utility of contract of porte-fort 51 
 
 English law as to person who professes to be an agent though he 
 
 has no authority 52 
 
 OHAPTEE III. 
 
 STIPULATIONS FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES OR THE 
 
 STIPULATION POUR AUTRUI 53 — 91 
 
 History of the stipulation pour autrui 53 
 
 Modern applications of the stipulation pour autrui 55 
 
 Public subscriptions 58 
 
 Many other cases '. °* 
 
 ight of the third party for whom a benefit is stipulated 60 
 
 (1) Theory of the offer 62 
 
 (2) Theory of implied assignment 64 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. V 
 CHAPTER III— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Eight of the third party for whom 1 a benefit is stipulated— continued. 
 
 (3) Theory of negotiorum gestio 65 
 
 (4) Theory of the droit propre 66 
 
 Theory of droit propre accepted in German Code 68 
 
 Characteristics of the third party's right 69 
 
 2 Effects of assent 72 
 
 How may the third party declare his assent ? 73 
 
 If the legal representative of the third party is the stipulator 
 himself, can he give the necessary assent for the third 
 
 party ? ^3 
 
 Assent does not need to be intimated to stipulator 74 
 
 JWno can be a beneficiary under the stipulation? 75 
 
 Determinate persons 75 
 
 Indeterminate or future persons 76 
 
 Cases where beneficiary is indeterminable at date of contract ... 78 
 
 Future persons 80 
 
 Matter dealt with in many countries by legislation 86 
 
 Eights of creditors in the case of insurance for a third party ... 87 
 What is the effect of the rescission of a contract in which a 
 benefit was stipulated for a third party who has assented 
 
 to it? 87 
 
 Comparison with English law 89 
 
 Common law as to the persons affected by contract 89 
 
 American law less rigorous as to relativity of contracts 91 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS AND ACTIONS BY 
 
 HIS CREDITORS -. 92 — 104 
 
 Whatever is recovered by the action falls into the patrimony of 
 
 the debtor 98 
 
 Any defence which is good as against the debtor himself is good 
 
 as against the creditor 99 
 
 Can the creditor sue for an amount greater than his own claim 
 
 against the debtor? 100 
 
 What are the rights and actions which creditors can exercise ? ... 100 
 Eight of creditors of incapable person to bring action on the 
 
 ground of incapacity 102 
 
 Eight to exercise a choice 103 
 
 Eights purely personal are exceptional 104 
 
VI TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 PAGE 
 THE PAULIAN ACTION 105—123 
 
 History of the Paulian action 106 
 
 Conditions of Paulian action 107 
 
 The act challenged must have caused prejudice 109 
 
 Property alienated must have formed part of debtor's estate 110 
 
 Debtor's estate must be diminished Ill 
 
 Only prior creditors have a right to the Paulian action 112 
 
 Proof of fraud in onerous transactions 113 
 
 Onerous grantees preferred to gratuitous grantees 114 
 
 Is the contract onerous or gratuitous ? 115 
 
 Effect of Paulian action as to sub-purchasers 116 
 
 Effect of the Paulian action as among the creditors 120 
 
 Prescription of Paulian action 123 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE 124 — 139 
 
 Different kinds of simulation 124 
 
 Rules as to actes deguises 125 
 
 Rules of evidence 12' 
 
 (1) When the action is between the parties to the deed ... 127 
 
 (2) When the action is by a third party 128 
 
 Effect of simulation as between the parties 129 
 
 Effect of simulation as regards third parties 131 
 
 Conflict between the ayants-cause of the apparent owner and the 
 
 creditors of the party who has granted a contre-lettre... 134 
 Distinction between the action en simulation and the Paulian 
 
 action 137 
 
 Distinction between the action en simulation and the indirect 
 
 action 1 39 
 
 CHAPTER VII. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT 140—162 
 
 Nul ne doit s'enrichir injustement au prejudice d'autrui 142 
 
 Quasi-contracts 142 
 
 Criticism of the term quasi-contract 143 
 
 German Code avoids term quasi-contract ' 145 
 
 Distinction between quasi-contract and implied contract 146 
 
 Proof of quasi-contracts 146 
 
 Negotiorum gestio or gestion d'affaires 148 
 
 Analogy between gestion d'affaires and mandate 149 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. VII 
 CHAPTER VII.— continued. 
 
 PACE 
 
 Conditions of gestion d'affaires 150 
 
 Is gestion confined to the doing of juridical acts ? 151 
 
 Is it essential that the gestion shall be unknown to the maitre? ... 152 
 
 Egyptian law 153 
 
 Knowledge of incapable person is immaterial 153 
 
 Must be intention to act on behalf of another and benefit re- 
 sulting 154 
 
 Benefit does not need to be subsisting at date of action 155 
 
 Who may be sued by third party 155 
 
 What is included under reimbursement? 155 
 
 Does the maitre need to have contractual capacity? 157 
 
 Does the gerant need to have contractual capacity? 158 
 
 Examples of negotiorum gestio 159 
 
 Assistance to ship in distress 160 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence 162 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO 163 — 186 
 
 Special applications of principle in French and Egyptian Codes. 166 
 
 The name actio de in rem verso 168 
 
 Miscellaneous illustrations from the French jurisprudence 169 
 
 Improvement on immovable held in indivision 172 
 
 Doctrine of general average or avaries communes 172 
 
 Is principle of avaries communes confined to maritime law? ... 173 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence 174 
 
 Attempt to determine the principles governing the matter 175 
 
 Confusion between action de in rem verso and action on gestion 
 
 d'affaires 176 
 
 Theory that source of obligation is delictual 177 
 
 Theory that source of obligation is the creation of value 178 
 
 Conditions of the action de in rem verso as determined by the 
 
 French jurisprudence 179 
 
 (1) The enrichment 180 
 
 (2) The enrichment must be a direct consequence of the 
 
 prejudice suffered by the plaintiff 181 
 
 (3) The defendant must not have a just cause for retaining 
 
 the enrichment without payment 182 
 
 (4) The enrichment must be subsisting 184 
 
 The action de in rem verso is a subsidiary action 185 
 
 Comparison with other laws 185 
 
Vlll TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER IX. 
 
 PAGE 
 THE QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE ...187—200 
 
 Repetition when there was no error 188 
 
 Payment made in error 189 
 
 Destruction of the title • 190 
 
 Onus of proof 191 
 
 (1) Payment 192 
 
 (2) No debt 192 
 
 (3) Error 193 
 
 English law as to quasi-contracts 196 
 
 Theory of implied contract 197 
 
 English illustrations of claims not arising from contract 198 
 
 Wrongs 200 
 
 CHAPTER X. 
 
 OF OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM THE LAW SOLELY ...201 — 205 
 
 Alimentary provisions 201 
 
 Other obligations arising by law 202 
 
 Obligation of alimony in Egyptian codes 203 
 
 Analysis of Article 155 203 
 
 Comparison with the Mohammedan law 203 
 
 Analysis of Article 156 204. 
 
 Comparison with the Mohammedan law 204 
 
 Code speaks only of ascendants, descendants and spouses 205 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence 205 
 
 CHAPTER XI. 
 
 PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEURE 206 — 218 
 
 Mise en demeure 207 
 
 When a date has been fixed for performance 207 
 
 Mise en demeure in commercial matters 207 
 
 How the debtor is put in default 208 
 
 Where no mise en demeure is necessary 210 
 
 (a) Performance impossible 211 
 
 English law as to this 2^.2 
 
 Putting in default presupposes possibility of performance... 2l2 
 
 (b) Law may declare mise en demeure unnecessary 213 
 
 (c) Stipulation may make mise en demeure unnecessary ... 214 
 Waiver of right to claim without mise en demeure 214 
 
 (d) No mise en demeure necessary when action based on 
 
 wrong-doing 215 
 
 Effects of putting in default 215 
 
 Mise en demeure in other codes 217 
 
 No mise en demeure required in English law 218 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. IX 
 CHAPTER XII. 
 
 PAGE 
 REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT 219—243 
 
 (1) The action for rescission or resolution of the contract 221 
 
 The tacit resolutory condition 221 
 
 The exceptio non adimpleti contractus 222 
 
 Court has discretion to refuse resolution 222 
 
 (2) Maintenance of contract partially executed and damages for 
 
 inexecutei part 224 
 
 (3) Substituted performance 224 
 
 (4) Specific performance 224 
 
 (5) Damages -'-'^ 
 
 Want of precision of the codes 224 
 
 (a) Obligation to pay or to deliver a specific thing 226 
 
 (b) Obligation to do or not to do 227 
 
 (3) Substituted performance 227 
 
 (c) Cases where judgment takes place of performance 227 
 
 (4) When can specific performance be claimed 229 
 
 Can creditor always insist on demolition of 
 
 buildings ? 229 
 
 Fait personnel cannot be specifically enforced 230 
 
 Illustrations of cases where specific performance of 
 
 the contract may be demanded 231 
 
 Specific performance of obligation to grant a servi- 
 tude ■ 232 
 
 Specific performance of contract of lease of thing ... 233 
 
 Specific performance of promise to grant deed .... 233 
 In previous cases personal intervention of debtor is 
 
 not necessary 233 
 
 Cases where specific performance cannot be de- 
 manded 234 
 
 Astrein tes 2o4 
 
 May the court order specific performance subject to payment of 
 
 a penalty ? 234 
 
 Extension by the jurisprudence of the principle of astreintes ... 236 
 
 Illustrations from the jurisprudence 238 
 
 Criticism of the jurisprudence 241 
 
 Astreintes in Egyptian jurisprudence 241 
 
 Enforcement of specific performance in other laws 243 
 
 CHAPTER XIII. 
 
 DAMAGES FOR BREACH OF PECUNIARY OBLIGATION ...244—249 
 
 Special damages in case of bad faith 246 
 
 German and Swiss laws as to this 246 
 
 Exceptions to rule that only legal interest is due 247 
 
 Compound interest 248 
 
 English law as to interest on money-debts 249 
 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER XIV. 
 
 PAGE 
 DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT NOT BEING 
 
 A CONTRACT TO PAY A SUM OF MONEY 250 — 260 
 
 If the loss sustained is a moral loss only, can the creditor claim 
 
 damages ? 252 
 
 English law 255 
 
 Direct and immediate consequence 255 
 
 Distinction based on absence of fraud 256 
 
 Damages for that which could have been foreseen 257 
 
 Illustrations of the rule as to damages which might have been 
 
 foreseen 258 
 
 Distinction in other laws 259 
 
 Clause of penalty 260 
 
 CHAPTER XV. 
 
 STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY ...261—285 
 
 Restrictive interpretation 261 
 
 Debtor cannot stipulate against his own dol or faute lourde 261 
 
 Stipulations of exoneration for fault of prepose 263 
 
 Stipulations of immunity for one's own ordinary negligence or 
 
 the ordinary negligence of one's prepose 264 
 
 Concurrence of faute contractuelle and faute delictuelle in other 
 
 systems of law 266 
 
 Is it a universal rule of the French law that a man by contract 
 
 cannot relieve himself from liability for a quasi-delict ? ... 267 
 
 Egyptian cases in contract of carriage 270 
 
 Special reasons of public policy in regard to contracts of carriage. 271 
 
 Different rule in England as to gratuitous passengers 273 
 
 Public policy as to carriage of goods 273 
 
 The question ought to be one of reasonableness 274 
 
 English law 274 
 
 Clauses of exoneration in maritime law 275 
 
 Laws of other countries 276 
 
 Post-office and telegrams 276 
 
 Post-office letters 276 
 
 Telegrams sent by private companies 277 
 
 Telegrams sent by public service 278 
 
 Egyptian law 278 
 
 Contracts by which a workman renounces beforehand his right 
 
 to claim damages for personal injuries 279 
 
 Other cases in which advantage has been taken of a position 
 
 of superiority 280 
 
 In other cases freedom of contract should be allowed 280 
 
 Tendency of recent French jurisprudence 281 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. XI 
 
 CHAPTER XY.— continued. 
 
 PAG] 
 
 Clauses of non-responsibility in other laws 282 
 
 (1) English law 282 
 
 (2) American law 284 
 
 (3) German law 284 
 
 (4) Swiss law 285 
 
 CHAPTER. XVI. 
 
 .NON-PERFORMANCE OF CONTRACT WITHOUT FAULT OF 
 
 DEBTOR 286 — 327 
 
 (1) Exceptional cases 286 
 
 (a) Express stipulation of warranty 286 
 
 (b) Implied warranty 286 
 
 (c) Warranty of carrier and hotel-keeper against theft ... 287 
 
 (2) General rule that damages are due 287 
 
 Supervening impossibility of performance 287 
 
 Force majeure in law of responsibility and in law of prescription. 290 
 Cas fortuit and force majeure include both objective impossibility 
 
 and subjective impossibility 290 
 
 Attempted distinction between the legal effects of force majeure 
 
 and those of cas fortuit 291 
 
 Criticism of new theory : 293 
 
 Essential characteristics of fortuitous event 293 
 
 Event founded upon as force majeure must not have been brought 
 
 about by any act of the debtor 294 
 
 Event must be impossible to foresee 294 
 
 Impossibility must be absolute 296 
 
 The impossibility must continue 296 
 
 Debtor who foresees the inexecution must do his best to minimise 
 
 its effects 296 
 
 Debtor not bound to take an altogether unusual precaution 297 
 
 Force majeure a question of fact 298 
 
 Illustrations of force majeure ' 298 
 
 (a) Events due to the forces of nature 298 
 
 Destruction of specific thing to be delivered 299 
 
 Alteration of physical conditions rendering performance 
 
 impossible 299 
 
 Fire as force majeure 299 
 
 Presumption against lessee in French law 300 
 
 No presumption against lessee in Egyptian law 301 
 
 Rule in Egyptian law 301 
 
 Sickness or epidemic as force majeure 302 
 
 (b) Events caused by the act of man 303 
 
 Special rule as to paid depositary 304 
 
 Special liability of hotel-keeper not to be extended by 
 
 analogy 305 
 
Xll TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER XVI.— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Illustrations of force majeure — continued. 
 
 War, invasion, &c 306 
 
 Fait du prince 306 
 
 Force majeure must create an impossibility 307 
 
 War as force majeure 307 
 
 Criticism of the jurisprudence and proposals to change the 
 
 law 313 
 
 Strikes 314 
 
 Onus of proof of fortuitous event 315 
 
 Effect of fortuitous event 316 
 
 Fortuitous event in contract of lease 317 
 
 Right to rebut defence of force majeure may be lost by acquies- 
 cence in non-performance 318 
 
 Acquiescence in non-performance 318 
 
 Comparison with other laws 318 
 
 Swiss Code 318 
 
 German Code 318 
 
 English law as to impossibility of performance 320 
 
 Extension of this principle 321 
 
 English law as to supervening incapacity to render personal 
 
 servi ces 323 
 
 Impossibility of performance does not cause the contract to be 
 
 rescinded ab initio 323 
 
 In English law war does not in itself necessarily create impossi- 
 bility of performance 324 
 
 Statutory power to avoid contracts 325 
 
 Force majeure, compared with "Act of God" 326 
 
 CHAPTER XVII. 
 
 CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS 328 — 349 
 
 Different kinds of obligations 328 
 
 Suspensive condition 329 
 
 Resolutive condition 329 
 
 (1) Event must not have already occurred 329 
 
 (2) Event future but certain 330 
 
 (3) Event impossible 331 
 
 (4) Event unlawful 331 
 
 (5) Event left to free choice of promisor 332 
 
 Effects of the condition 335 
 
 Conditional right is not mere hope 335 
 
 Nothing yet due pending the condition 336 
 
 Conditional creditor may do conservatory acts 337 
 
 Conditional creditor's right protected if conditional debtor is 
 
 insolvent .'. 337 
 
 Conditional seller mav revindicate if condition fails 338 
 
TABLE OF CONTENT*. Xlll 
 CHAPTER XVII .— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 The fulfilment and the failure of conditions 338 
 
 Conditions strictly interpreted 339 
 
 Condition that act shall be performed by particular person 340 
 
 What if no time is fixed for performance ? 340 
 
 Fraudulent prevention of fulfilment 341 
 
 Comparison with other laws 343 
 
 The effects of the failure of the condition 345 
 
 The effects of the fulfilment of the condition 345 
 
 Discussion as to retroactivity 347 
 
 The risk 348 
 
 CHAPTER XVIII. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM 350—360 
 
 Repetition of debt paid before the term arrives 351 
 
 Presumption that term is in favour of the debtor 353 
 
 Computation of the term 354 
 
 The risk during the term 354 
 
 Loss of right to claim the term 355 
 
 Does the insolvency of a non-trader produce the same effect as 
 
 the bankruptcy of a trader? 356 
 
 How is insolvency to be determined ? 357 
 
 Does it need to be declared by a judgment ? 357 
 
 Diminution of securities by the debtor 359 
 
 ff /I 
 
 CHAPTER XIX. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS IN WHICH THERE ARE SEVERAL OBJECTS AND 
 
 SEVERAL SUBJECTS 361—377 
 
 Obligations simple and composite 361 
 
 Obligations simple and multiple 362 
 
 Alternative obligations 362 
 
 Alternative obligation distinguished from conjunctive or facul- 
 tative obligation 363 
 
 In an alternative obligation who has the choice? 363 
 
 Refusal to exercise the option 364 
 
 German Code as to this 365 
 
 Can the French or the Egyptian Courts transfer the choice to 
 
 the other party ? 365 
 
 Transmissibility of the option 366 
 
 How is the option to be declared ? 366 
 
 Does the alternative obligation operate an immediate transfer 
 
 of the property ? 368 
 
XIV TAHLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER XIX.— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Retroactive effect of the choice .' 368 
 
 Obligation may appear to be alternative without really being so. 370 
 
 Effect of the impossibility of executing one of the alternatives ... 371 
 
 (a) When the option belongs to the debtor 373 
 
 (b) When the option belongs to the creditor 376 
 
 CHAPTER XX. 
 
 FACULTATIVE OBLIGATIONS 378 — 380 
 
 ■Jfr 
 
 Definition 378 
 
 Distinction between the facultative obligation and the alternative 
 
 obligation 378 
 
 Examples of facultative obligations 379 
 
 Practical consequences of the distinction between facultative and 
 
 alternative obligations 379 
 
 CHAPTER XXI. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE 381 — 402 
 
 Definition 382 
 
 Where should this subject be placed? 382 
 
 No form prescribed for clause of penalty 382 
 
 Purpose of clauses of penalty 383 
 
 Clause of penalty strictly construed 383 
 
 Clause of penalty cannot defeat legal restrictions on rate of 
 
 interest 383 
 
 Position in the Egyptian Code 384 
 
 Obligation with penal clause distinguished from facultative 
 
 obligation 385 
 
 Obligation with penal clause distinguished from conditional 
 
 obligation , 385 
 
 Accessory character of the penal clause 386 
 
 (1) Must be valid principal obligation 386 
 
 (2) The nullity of the penal clause does not involve the 
 
 nullity of the principal obligation 388 
 
 (3) Creditor may claim performance of principal obligation... 389 
 
 (4) The penalty comes in place of the damages 389 
 
 Penalty for delay 389 
 
 Doubt as to whether penalty is for delay or for non-performance. 390 
 
 Penalty not due unless debtor is in fault or in default 391 
 
 Can the court fix a delai de grace? 392 
 
 Can damages be claimed in excess of the penalty stipulated or 
 
 can the penalty be reduced if excessive? 392 
 
 Cases where amount of penalty may bo varied 394 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. XV 
 CHAPTER XXI— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Can the creditor claim the penalty if the debtor prove that no 
 
 damages have been suffered ? 397 
 
 Conflicting opinion "no damages no penalty" 399 
 
 Penal clause in other legal systems 401 
 
 Indivisibility as applied to obligations with a clause of penalty. 402 
 
 CHAPTER XXII. 
 
 JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS 403—430 
 
 (a) Joint and several creditors 404 
 
 Release 406 
 
 Interruption and suspension of prescription 406 
 
 (b) Joint and several debtors 407 
 
 Presumption against joint and several liability 409 
 
 Does the presumption against joint and several liability apply 
 
 to commercial matters ? 409 
 
 Joint and several liability by law 410 
 
 Conventional joint and several liability 413 
 
 Effects of joint and several liability among the debtors 414 
 
 (a) Effects of principle that each debtor is liable for whole 
 
 debt 414 
 
 (b) Effects of theory that each debtor has mandate 415 
 
 Consequences of theory pf mandate 416 
 
 Exceptions which a joint and several debtor may plead 
 
 against the creditor 417 
 
 Personal exceptions 417 
 
 Exceptions common to all the debtors 418 
 
 Exceptions personal to another debtor 418 
 
 " Personal exception " does not mean same thing here as 
 
 in case of surety 418 
 
 Confusion 419 
 
 Compensation 419 
 
 Chose jugee 420 
 
 Release 422 
 
 What is the effect of the release from the solidarity if one of 
 
 the co-debtors becomes insolvent? 424 
 
 Is the effect of a release from the solidarity to oblige the 
 
 creditor to deduct the share of the debtor released ? . . . 427 
 
 Release of the debt 428 
 
 Alleged imperfect solidarity 428 
 
 Two debtors may be liable each for the whole debt without any 
 
 solidarity 429 
 
 Effects of joint and several liability as among the co-debtors 
 
 themselves 429 
 
XVI TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIII. PAGE 
 
 DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS ,431 — 442 
 
 (1) Obligations indivisible by nature 432 
 
 (2) Obligations indivisible by agreement 434 
 
 English law as to this ....(^ 435 
 
 Indivisibility on one side only 435 
 
 The effects of indivisibility ' 437 
 
 Comparison between indivisibility and joint and several liability. 442 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV. 
 
 EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS 443 — 557 
 
 (1) Performance or payment 444 
 
 By whom performance may be made 445 
 
 Person paying must have capacity 448 
 
 To whom payment must be made 449 
 
 Performance made to the person holding the right to claim 
 
 execution of the obligation 450 
 
 Payment cannot prejudice seizures 451 
 
 Performance must be of thing due and cannot be made in 
 
 part 451 
 
 Place of performance 452 
 
 Expenses of payment . > 454 
 
 Proof of payment 454 
 
 Payment with subrogation 455 
 
 Special points of difference between Erench and Egyptian 
 
 laws 457 
 
 Conventional subrogation 458 
 
 Legal subrogation 460 
 
 Purchaser of immoveable who pays price to hypothecary 
 
 creditors 461 
 
 Persons liable with or for the debtor 462 
 
 Effects of subrogation 463 
 
 Various theories of subrogation 464 
 
 Practical consequences of the difference of theory 465 
 
 Has Egyptian Code adopted new theory? 466 
 
 Imputation of payments 466 
 
 Debtor cannot injure rights of creditors 467 
 
 Exception to rule that debtor can make imputation 467 
 
 Imputation by the creditor 468 
 
 Legal imputation 469 
 
 Comparison with other laws 470 
 
 Effect of the impossibility of finding the creditor in order to pay 
 
 him or of the refusal by the creditor to take payment ... 470 
 
 Tender and payment into court 470 
 
 Obligation to pay a sum of money or to deliver a specific 
 
 corporeal thing 471 
 
 Tender at bar of court v 474 
 
 Action to have tender declared valid 474 
 
 Obligation to do or not to do 474 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. XV11 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV.— continued, 
 
 PAGE 
 
 (1) Performance or payment — continued. 
 
 Obligation to deliver an immoveable 475 
 
 Obligation to deliver an indeterminate thing 475 
 
 (2) Dissolution by the performance of the obligation becoming 
 
 impossible 470 
 
 Contract may imply that risk was to be on seller 478 
 
 The loss of thing due an instance of impossibility of per- ' 
 
 formance 478 
 
 Application of rule against unjust enrichment 479 
 
 Theory of risk in the Egyptian law 480 
 
 (3) Novation 482 
 
 (1) Simple novation 484 
 
 (2) Delegation 484 
 
 Expromission 484 
 
 (3) Novation by change of creditor 485 
 
 Parties to novation must be capable 485 
 
 Novation not presumed 486 
 
 Must be valid debt to novate 488 
 
 New debt must be substituted 488 
 
 Effects of novation 488 
 
 Transfer of securities to new debt 489 
 
 No transfer of securities to property of new debtor 490 
 
 Is the old debtor's consent necessary to transfer securities ? ... 490 
 
 Protection of third parties 491 
 
 Novation in case of joint and several debt or debt secured 
 
 by a surety 491 
 
 Delegation 492 
 
 Meaning of express discharge 493 
 
 Delegation distinguished from novation 493 
 
 Distinction between perfect delegation and imperfect 
 
 delegation 494 
 
 Indication of person to pay or to receive payment 495 
 
 Distinction between novation by change of creditor and 
 
 assignment of a claim 495 
 
 (4) Release 496 
 
 Release may be tacit 497 
 
 (5) Compensation. 499 
 
 (a) Legal compensation 500 
 
 Can court declare compensation ex officio? 500 
 
 Compensation first pleaded in appeal 501 
 
 What debts can be compensated 501 
 
 (1) The debts must be reciprocal 501 
 
 (2) The debts which are compensated must be of the 
 
 same kind, or be fungible 503 
 
 (3) The two debts must both be demandable 504 
 
 w. — VOL. II. b 
 
XV111 TABLE OF CONTENTS. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV.— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 (5) Compensation — continued. 
 
 What debts can be compensated — continued. 
 
 (4c) The debts must be liquidated 504 
 
 Debt uncertain 505 
 
 Debt not liquid 505 
 
 (5) The debts must be payable in the same place 50(5 
 
 Exceptional cases in which legal compensation is not per- 
 mitted 507 
 
 Eule not necessary in case of loan for use 500 
 
 Debt not liable to seizure 510 
 
 Effects of legal compensation 510 
 
 Imputation 511 
 
 Compensation not to prejudice third parties 511 
 
 Assignment 512 
 
 Arrestment '. 513 
 
 Bankruptcy 513 
 
 Eight to renounce compensation 514 
 
 (b) Facultative compensation 515 
 
 Compensation in other laws 515 
 
 (6) Confusion 516 
 
 Confusion usually caused by succession 517 
 
 No confusion when benefit of inventory 518 
 
 Extinction of principal debt by confusion extinguishes acces- 
 sory debt ' 518 
 
 French law as to confusion does not apply in the case of 
 
 Mohammedan successions 520 
 
 (7) Prescription 521 
 
 Acquisitive prescription and extinctive prescription 521 
 
 Law of prescription based upon public policy 522 
 
 Full explanation of acquisitive prescription belongs to law 
 
 of property '522 
 
 Rules common to acquisitive and extinctive prescription ... 523 
 
 The delays of prescription 523 
 
 Long prescription 523 
 
 Prescription of five years 524 
 
 Restitution of fruits not governed by five years' prescription. 524 
 
 The five years* prescription applies to moratory interest .... 525- 
 
 Prescription of 360 days 527 
 
 Debtor must be put upon his oath 528 
 
 Difference between French and Egyptian law 528 
 
 ferment de credulite 528 
 
 Prescription may be pleaded at any stage of the proceedings. 529 
 
 The judge cannot ex officio give effect to prescription 530 
 
 Calculation of prescriptive period 530 
 
 Point of departure of extinctive prescription 532 
 
 Conditional debt 532 
 
 Action in warranty 533 
 
 Debt subject to term 533 
 
TABLE OF CONTENTS. XIX 
 CHAPTER XXIV— continued. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 (7) Prescription — confinmed. 
 
 Prescription does not run till debt is exigible 534 
 
 When the debt is divided into fractions or into separate 
 
 items 534 
 
 Doubt with regard to sums due to physicians 536 
 
 French law 53fi 
 
 Egyptian law 530 
 
 What rule would apply in the Native Courts 537 
 
 Retroactive effect of prescription 538 
 
 According to what calendar is the prescriptive period 
 
 reckoned ? 539 
 
 Renunciation of prescription 540 
 
 Renunciation in advance is contrary to public policy 541 
 
 Is the rule prohibiting renunciation an absolute one? 542 
 
 Is an agreement to suspend prescription a renunciation in 
 
 advance ? 543 
 
 Renunciation of acquired prescription 543 
 
 Renunciation during the course of prescription 544 
 
 Renunciation may be tacit 544 
 
 Tacit renunciation must be en connaissance de cause 540 
 
 Renunciation of prescription is not an alienation 547 
 
 Renunciation of the right to claim acquisitive prescription 
 
 requires capacity to alienate 548 
 
 Capacity for renunciation of extinctive prescription 548 
 
 Right of creditors and other third parties to revoke a pre- 
 scription which has been renounced 549 
 
 Can parties other than creditors sometimes invoke prescrip- 
 tion which has been renounced ? 550 
 
 Interruption of prescription 551 
 
 Acts of interruption 551 
 
 Acts of acknowledgment 552 
 
 Effects of interruption 553 
 
 Suspension of prescription 553 
 
 Causes of suspension 554 
 
 May there be other causes of suspension? 554 
 
 Other modes of extinction 556 
 
 (1) Expiration of the time limited by the parties for its 
 
 duration 556 
 
 (2) Death of the creditor and debtor in certain cases 550 
 
 Concordance 559 
 
 Inprx 571 
 
ci/fc. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 
 
 Confusion in the French Code between effects of contracts 
 and effects of obligations. 
 
 The French Code, after dealing with the interpretation of con- 
 tracts, has a section which is headed Of the effect of contracts 
 in regard to third parties. (C. C. F. 1165.) 
 
 And the Egyptian codes, following the same order, give 
 articles of a similar nature. (C. C. N. 141 — 143; C. C. M. 
 202—204.) 
 
 * But the French Code contains in another place a chapter headed 
 Of the effect of obligations, of which the first article is awkwardly 
 placed. (C. C. F. 1134.) 
 
 It would have been more natural to put this article in the 
 same section with articles 1165 — 1167. 
 
 In this respect the Civil Code of Quebec has improved upon the 
 arrangement by having one section, Of the effect of contracts, 
 in which the effects are given as between the parties themselves 1 , 
 and two other sections which discuss the effects of contracts in 
 regard to third persons, including la stipulation pour autrui, the 
 indirect action by creditors, and the Paulian Action. (C. 0. Q. 
 1022—1040.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code, meagre as it is, seems to intend to reproduce 
 the French law. (See Halton, I, p. 333.) 
 
 We must distinguish between the effects of contracts and the 
 effects of obligations. 
 
 The effect of a contract is to create obligations. The contract 
 brings into existence a legal relation between the parties. If it 
 is a synallagmatic contract it produces obligations on both 6ides, 
 whereas if it is a unilateral contract it produces one obligation 
 only. It must also be remembered that some contracts operate 
 
 w.— vol. n. 1 
 
2 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 also a transfer of property, as when the owner of a corps certain 
 pells it. (C. C. E. 91/145.) 
 
 The effect of an obligation is to give the creditor the right 
 to enforce the performance. With this we are not just now 1 
 concerned. 
 
 Effects of contracts as between the parties. 
 
 The French Code says Agreements legally formed take the 
 place of Jaw as between the parties. 
 
 They cannot be revoked except by their mutual consent or for 
 causes which the law authorises. They must be executed in good 
 (a; lit. (C. C. F. 1134.)^ 
 
 This article of the French Code is headed Of the effect of 
 obligations, but this is a mistake. The article deals entirely with 
 the effect of contracts. In saying that the agreement takes the 
 place of law between the parties, the Code means merely that the 
 agreement becomes a sort of private law to which the parties 
 have voluntarily subjected themselves, and that when the courts 
 are satisfied that the agreement was legally entered into and is 
 not such an agreement as is prohibited by law the courts must 
 enforce it. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Control, p. 744. Supra, I, 
 p. 361.) 
 
 The Code of Quebec expresses the law better by saying Con- 
 tracts produce obligations and sometimes have the effect of 
 discharging or modifying other contracts . They have also the 
 effect in some cases of transferring the right of property. 
 
 They can be set aside only by the mutual consent of the parties 
 or for causes established by law. (C. C. Q. 1022.) 
 
 Contracts make the law between the parties. 
 
 Neither the Code of Quebec nor the Egyptian Code has repro- 
 duced this provision of the French Code; probably because it 
 seemed to be too theoretical for a code. 
 
 The German Code, however, lias a somewhat similar declara- 
 tion. It says: Contracts aire to be interpreted in the manner 
 required by loyalty and reciprocal confidence taken in connection 
 with the usages recognised in business (art. 157). 
 
 This does not mean that the court can set up an ideal contract 
 and substitute it for the will of the parties. On the con- 
 trary, it is the will x of the parties which must be discovered and 
 to which effect must be given. 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 3 
 
 But the court is entitled to assume that neither of the parties 
 intended to take advantage of the other, and that each of them 
 Iiad a right to expect that the other would honestly and fairly 
 fulfil his obligation. 
 
 The broad principle that contracts make the law between the 
 parties and that they are to be executed in good faith, although 
 not stated in the Codes of Quebec or of Egypt, is just as much a 
 part of those laws as it is of the French law. (Of. supra, I, 
 p. 358 and p. 361.) 
 
 It is a general principle laid down in the Roman law on the 
 subject, and it has been held in France that it applies to contracts 
 anterior to the Code. (Dig. 16. 3. 1. 6; Cass. 6 mars 1876, 
 D. 76. 1. 193.) 
 
 In saying that a contract makes the law between the parties, 
 we mean (1) that it overrides any general provision of law, not 
 being a law of public order, and (2) that the court is bound to 
 give effect to the contract as it stands and is not entitled to modify 
 it in order to make it more equitable. (Cass. 19 mare 1913, D. 
 1916. 1. 238; supra, I, p. 358 and p. 361.) 
 
 Modification of charitable foundations. 
 
 The interesting and difficult question as to the power of the 
 courts to "vary r ' charitable foundations when a change of cir- 
 cumstances makes it impossible or inexpedient to carry out the 
 original purpose, is a question which can only be noted in this 
 place. (See Demogue, E., in Rev. Trim. 1907, p. 287.) 
 
 The English courts exercise a power of this kind. It is spoken 
 of as the principle or rule of cy-pres — that is, of carrying out the 
 original purpose as nearly as possible. {Moggi'id-ge v. Thackwell, 
 1792, 7 Vesey, 36, 2 R. R. 140; Jarman on Wills, 6th ed. 1, 
 p. 233; Halsbury, Laws of England, vo. Charities, n. 333; Snell, 
 Equity, 17th ed. 95.) 
 
 Contract changes legal situation of parties. 
 
 Under any system of law which recognises freedom of contract 
 the parties who have made a contract are allowed to modify their 
 legal relations. 
 
 They make a law for themselves as regards the particular 
 matter with which they are dealing, and this exercise of their free 
 will is permitted by the law. 
 
 1 (2) 
 
4 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But, as Ave have already seen, this is subject to the limitation 
 thai they cannot contract themselves out of a law of public order,, 
 or, in other words, their contract must not be one which is for- 
 bidden. 
 
 Interpretation of contract is question of fact. 
 
 The rule that the contract forms the law between the parties 
 does not mean that the interpretation of a contract is a question 
 of law. 
 
 On the contrary, it is a question of fact; the court has to dis- 
 cover the intention of the parties in each particular case. 
 
 This is in France an important distinction, because the Cour 
 de Cassation has no power to review a judgment as to facts. It 
 can only correct errors of law into which the lower courts have 
 fallen . In the construction of contracts it is not always easy to 
 say what is fact and what is law, and in France somewhat fine 
 distinctions have been drawn. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 336; Hue, 
 7, n. 88.) 
 
 With these we are not concerned, because with us, in civil 
 matters, there is an appeal both as to facts and law. In criminal 
 appeals the Courts of Appeal in Egypt are courts of cassation in 
 the French sense. (C. Crim. Proc. N. art. 229; Code Crim. 
 Invest. M. art. 153. See C. A. Alex. 17 janv. 1906, B. L. J. 
 XVIII, 95.) In saying that agreements are to be performed in 
 good faith the French Code means to declare that it rejects the 
 distinction of the Roman law between actions stricti juris and 
 actions bonce, fidei. (Hue, 7, n. 90; Fand. Frwiq. vo. Oblig.. 
 n. 7915; supra, I, p. 358 and p. 361.) 
 
 Exceptio non adimpleti contractus. 
 
 This article might also be used to support the doctrine which, 
 undoubtedly forms a part of the French law, that in every 
 synallagmatic contract the party asking for the execution of the 
 contract will not be entitled to a judgment unless he has performed 
 his own part of the contract or is ready to perform it. (See 
 Planiol, 2, n. 949; Cassin, B,., De I'Exception tiree de Vlnexecu- 
 tion, p. 440; Cass, 1 mai 1889, D. 90. 1. 470.) 
 
 This rule has been alreadjr explained in discussing the character- 
 of bilateral contracts. (Supra, I, p. 88.) 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 5 
 
 Modification of contract by parties. 
 
 It hardly needs to be stated that the parties to a contract may, C\ 
 as a general rule, put an end to it or modify it by a second contract. 
 They were free to make it and they are equally free to unmake it 
 or to change it. So long as the contract which modifies or dis- 
 charges a previous contract between the parties is not contrary to 
 public order or good morals it will receive effect . Nor does the law 
 require in all cases that the consent to modify or discharge a con- 
 tract shall be made in express terms. The parties may show by 
 their conduct that they have so agreed. 
 
 In other words, the consent to modify may be either tacit or 
 expressed . 
 
 Thus in a contract for the sale of coal, where the seller intimated 
 to the buyer that, owing to the outbreak of war, and Government 
 regulations in consequence thereof, he could not supply the coal, 
 and to this intimation the buyer made no reply, it was held that 
 he had acquiesced in the resiliation of the contract. (C. A. Alex. 
 11 avril 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 358.) 
 
 In a series of French cases it has been held that clauses of a 
 policy of insurance to the effect that the premium should be 
 portable, that is to say, that it should be the duty of the insured 
 to take the premiums to the company's agent, had been modified 
 by tacit agreement. ••*-> 
 
 The uniform practice of the agent to call and collect the pre- 
 miums when they fell due had been assented to by the insurer, and 
 by this tacit agreement the premium had become querable, that is, 
 it must be called for, and, accordingly, it was not in arrears until 
 demanded. (Cass. 4 nov. 1891, D. 92. 1. 313; D. N. C. C. IV, 
 p. 875, n. 1113, and p. 910, n. 158.) 
 
 And there are many cases in which the courts hold that a party 
 who was at first entitled to enforce a certain condition of a contract 
 has by his conduct waived his right to do so. The original con- 
 tract has been modified. (See Cass. 27 juillet 1892, D. 92. 1. 
 462.) So when the price is to be paid by instalments, it may be 
 stipulated that if any instalment is not paid at the time agreed 
 upon, this shall give the vendor the right s at once to demand pay- 
 ment of the whole balance due. 
 
 But if a vendor has on two occasions allowed the purchaser to 
 pay an overdue instalment, it may be held that he cannot on the 
 third occasion insist on his right to take nothing but the whole 
 balance. (C. A. 17 April 1912, O. B. XIII, n. 114. For an 
 
6 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 interesting example of a modification of a contract by implied 
 assent to a new condition, see Douai, 9 nov. 1899, D. 1901. 2. 46.) 
 
 But the renunciation of a right is never presumed, and, though 
 the renunciation of the right to enforce the contract — the waiver, 
 to use the technical term of the English law — -may be implied, it 
 •will not be implied unless the circumstances clearly indicate the 
 imtention not. to insist on the right in question. 
 AyA^ In insurance policies it is not uncommon to find clauses pro- 
 viding how certain conditions may be waived. For example, it 
 may be a condition of a fire policy that the assured must send 
 particulars of the loss within a certain number of days, and it 
 may be provided that this condition is not to be waived except in 
 writing and by the company's manager. An assurance company 
 has a large number of agents scattered over the country, and if 
 they were to be allowed to waive conditions made in favour of 
 the company it would be difficult to carry on the business of 
 insurance at all. 
 
 Most of these agents are merely agents for canvassing, whose, 
 business it is to persuade people to insure with the company, and to 
 collect and forward the premiums. Such agents do not dictate the 
 form of the contract or its terms, and it would be unreasonable that 
 they should have power to waive conditions which the company 
 has made. 
 
 Where no such condition is expressed in the policy the assured 
 does not forfeit his rights to the indemnity by failure to make the 
 declaration of the loss within the delay named, if his failure to do 
 so was at the request of the company's agent. Xancy, 8 dec. 
 1894, D. 95.2. 165.) 
 
 The rules as to this loss of contractual rights by waiver or 
 acquiescence form an important chapter in the law. It happens 
 frequently that a contract is modified in this way by the conduct 
 of the- parties, and that when one of them attempts to get it en- 
 forced by the courts it is held that he has no title to do so, because 
 he has shown by his conduct his intention not to insist upon his 
 legal rights under the contract, or, it may be, not to insist upon a 
 certain particular right which was thereby given to him. 
 
 The principle that the conduct of one of the parties may modify 
 
 the contract is illustrated in the case where the inexecution by 
 
 one party justifies the other party in refusing to execute the 
 
 >> ''' "^ contract on his side. (See supra, I, p. 88; Cass. 4 fevr. 1889, 
 
 D. 90. 1. 121.) 
 
 As a rule it is perfectly competent for a party to surrender a 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 7 
 
 right given to him by contract, but we must remember that ho 
 caiiiKj] surrender a right which is given to him by a law of public 
 order; so that, for instance, it could not be maintained that aQp^ 
 husband had by his conduct renounced any of the rights which the 
 law gives to him as a husband, or that a man who was a party to 
 a contract which was contrary to public policy or to good morals 
 had lost by his conduct the right to challenge its validity, for, as 
 has already been explained, it is a fundamental rule of the law 
 that one cannot by a private agreement modify a law of public 
 order and good morals. 
 
 This rule applies equally to a private agreement made in express 
 terms or to an agreement manifested by the conduct of parties. 
 (C. C. F. 6; C. C. Q. 13; Decree of Reorg. Native Courts, art. 
 28.) When a contract is contrary to public order the court is 
 bound ex mero motu to refuse all effect to it, and there can bo 
 no question of the party being barred by his conduct from 
 challenging the contract. (Larombiere, art. 1338, nos. 8 and 25; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1338, n. 31; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1933.) 
 
 Effect of modification or cancellation of contract as between 
 
 the parties. 
 
 When the parties modify their contract either expressly or by 
 implication they may do so in any way which suits them, pro- 
 vided they do not infringe the laws of public order. And, in like 
 maimer, when they agree to cancel their contract, they may deter- 
 mine what rights .each of them is to have. 
 
 The presumption is that when they cancel the contract they 
 intend the rights to be those existing at the date of the cancella- 
 tion, for till then the contract was in force, and unless the parties 
 have stated that they intended the cancellation to be retroactive, 
 it will not be presumed that they intended it to be so. 
 
 This has an important consequence in regard to the amount of 
 damages. If the parties have cancelled the contract, reserving 
 their respective right to damages, the presumption is that this 
 means the damages as at the date when the contract was cancelled. 
 
 "6 
 
 
 
 Effect of modification or cancellation as regards third parties, p. 
 
 Although the parties can, as between themselves, determine that 
 their contract shall come to an end, and even that it shall be as if 
 it had never existed, that is, that the cancellation shall be retro- 
 
8 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 active, the}' cannot. modify or extinguish rights which third parties 
 have acquired under the contract while it existed. 
 
 If the contract produced a transfer of property, the party who 
 by the contract became owner may have granted hypothecs or 
 created servitudes over the property, and the subsequent 
 revocation of the contract cannot affect the parties who have 
 acquired these rights. 
 
 Moreover, if there are by the fiscal law, dues to be paid on every 
 transfer of property, the contract which revoked the former one 
 is regarded as being a now transfer of property. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 1166.) 
 
 This principle will be explained more fully presently in speak- 
 ing of the effect of contracts as regards third parties, for the 
 modification of a contract is, in fact, a new contract. 
 
 Renewal of contract. 
 
 When a contract expires the parties are free to renew it upon 
 the same or upon different conditions. For instance, when a 
 lease expires, or a contract of fire insurance terminates at the end 
 of the year for which it was effected, if the parties agree to renew 
 it they do not continue to be subject to the old contract, but they 
 make a new one. But there are some contracts, such as those of 
 life-assurance, or of membership of a club, or of a trades-union, 
 which stand in a different position. So long as the party assured 
 pays the premium when it is due, or so long as the member of the 
 club or of the union pays his dues and satisfies the conditions of 
 membership, he is entitled to the continuance of the old contract, 
 unless, in the membership case, he lias been removed from the list 
 in accordance with the rules to which he submitted himself. 
 
 The contract in these cases is not renewed annually, it is kept 
 in force. 
 
 One of the parties is not free to modify it at the end of a year 
 without the consent of the other or without a change in the rules. 
 (See D. Rep. Pratique, Associations, n. 98; Aix, 23 nov. 1904, 
 D. 1905. 2. 121, and note by Planiol; Civ. 23 juin 1860, D. 
 60. 1. 243; Cass. 19 mars 1901, D. 1903. 1. 329; D. Rep. Prat. 
 Assurances, n. 259.) And it m&y be remarked in passing that 
 the distinction between these two classes of contracts is an impor- 
 tant one in the case where a statute declares that it is not to apply 
 to contracts existing at its date. For a contract of this type 
 continues to exist if it is kept in life in the manner provided. 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 9 
 
 Exceptions to rule that contracts can be modified or revoked 
 
 by parties. 
 
 Although the article in the French Code, now under considera- 
 tion (C. C. F. 1134), which we are taking in connection with 
 C. 0. F. 1165, says in general terms that contracts can be revoked 
 by the mutual consent of the parties, there are, nevertheless, excep- 
 tions to this rule. 
 
 There are some contracts, though not many, which in the French 
 law cannot be discharged or modified by the parties. Marriage 
 is a contract, or, perhaps, it would be more correct to say, it is 
 entered into by a contract; for by their contract, manifested in 
 the way which the law requires, the parties effect a change in 
 their status. As it has been well expressed, " Marriage is a status 
 of which the gate is a contract." 
 
 But, although the parties enter into this status by a contract, 
 they cannot by a contract put an end to it, for the French law does 
 not admit divorce by consent, nor can the parties modify the rights 
 of status which the law gives them. So also, the marriage-cove- 
 nants bj r which the patrimonial rights of the consorts are fixed 
 before the marriage, if they do not leave them to be regulated by 
 the general law, become irrevocable at the celebration of the mar- 
 riage, in such a way that the parties cannot surrender any of the 
 rights so given to them, or modify the marriage-covenants in 
 any way after the marriage. (C. C. F. 1395: C. C. Q. 1260.) 
 We do not attempt to explain the Mohammedan law on these 
 points. 
 
 Certain contracts can be revoked by one party or one party 
 may be released owing to change of circumstances. 
 
 It is clear that, as a general rule, a contract cannot be set aside 
 by one party only. There would be no virtue in contracts if 
 either party could resile from them at will. As the contract 
 takes two to make it, so it will take two to unmake it. (See the 
 interesting article in Rev. Trim. 1907, p. :245, on Modifications 
 aux oontrats par volonte unilaterale, b}^ M. Rene Demogue.) It 
 can be set aside without such mutual consent for certain causes, 
 viz., fraud, error, violence, and, in some cases, lesion. 
 
 Or it may be declared to have never existed for want of two 
 consenting minds or for lack of an object or of a lawful cause. 
 The law as to these matters has already been explained. But. 
 when there is a valid contract not tainted with any vice, the rule 
 
10 
 
 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 hat it stands good, unless both parties agree to discharge or 
 to vary it. This rule, however, is subject to certain exceptions 
 created by special provisions as to particular contracts. So a 
 mandate may be revoked, or, subject to certain conditions as to 
 damages, it may be renounced. (C. C. X. 52j2j 529; C. C. M. 
 640, 650; C. C. F. 2003, 2007: C. C. Q. 1755, 1759. Sec 
 B.-L. et Wahl, Mandat, n. 812; Demogue, in Eev. Trim. 1907, 
 p. 271.) So, likewise, the person who has given a thing to a 
 carrier for transport to A may, in some circumstances, forbid the 
 carrier to deliver the thing to A. (Cass. 15 now 1893, D. 94. 1. 
 273; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial 3, n. 
 584; Thaller, Traite EUm. n. 1165; Demogue, in Rev. Trim. 
 1907, p. 270.) The qualifications and details do not belong here. 
 
 And a partnership, unless for a fixed period, can be dissolved 
 at the will of any one of the partners, provided this renunciation 
 on his part is in good faith and is not made a contretemps, 
 that is at a moment when the dissolution would be unfair to the 
 other partner or partners. (C. C. E. 445/542; C. C. F. 1865; 
 C. C. Q. 1895: C. A. Alex. 3 dec. 1890. B. L. J. Ill, 43.; 
 So, likewise, a man who ha- let work to another to be done by 
 contract for a fixed price— -memihe a forf ait— or even, in the 
 Egyptian law, for a price settled according to the time occupied 
 or the work done, can at any time cancel the contract if he pays 
 the contractor his expenses' and damages according to the circum- 
 stances of the case. (C. C. E. 407/495; C. C. F. 1794; C. C. Q. 
 1691; C. A. Alex. 18 mars 1909; B. L. J. XXI, 254.) 
 
 Such a provision is necessary, for it might easily happen that 
 a man began to build a house, and then found that he had not 
 enough money to finish it, and, this being the reason, it does not 
 seem to make any difference whether the materials are supplied 
 by the owner of the building or by the contractor. (Cass. 5 janv. 
 1897, D. 97. 1. 89. See Demogue, in Rev. Trim. 1907, p. 267.) 
 
 But these cases are specially provided for in the code and are 
 exceptions to the rule. The French article also states that a 
 contract may be revoked for causes which the law authorises. 
 This is not at all a happy expression, but it means that there are 
 cases in which owin g to the conduct of the other party, or to some 
 changj of circumstances, the party acquires a right to Be relieved 
 of his contract. This is so when its performance becomes im- 
 possible by a fortuitous event, or when a party gets a contract 
 I dissolved on the ground of the non-fulfilment by the other party 
 of what he had promised. C. C. F. 1184; C. C. Q. 1065.) 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 11 
 
 Another example is the case of the lender of an article who 
 Bnds he has an urgent need for the article himself. By the French 
 law the lender can put an end to the contract by asking for the 
 return of the thing. (C. C. F. 1889; C. C. Q. 1774.) 
 
 And probably the Egyptian law is the same, though the code 
 is silent upon the point. (Grandmoulin, Contrats, p. 270. Cf. 
 German Code, art. 605; Stat. Keel. art. 804. 
 
 It has been suggested that it would be equitable to give the 
 courts a wider power to vary contracts, especially contracts of 
 long duration, when owing to some unexpected change of eircum- ^ 
 stances, their literal performance becomes very burdensome to one 
 party. (See Demogue, R., in Rev. Trim. 1907, p. 247 and 
 p. 309.) 
 
 It is probable, however, that such a change of the law would 
 do more harm than good, and would encourage undesirable liti- 
 gation. It is highly in the public interest that the security of 
 contracts should be maintained. (See supra, I. pp. 105 and 361.) 
 
 There is, notwithstanding, one important case in which there 
 is much to be said in favour of giving the courts power to modify 
 a contract. This is when the unexpected outbreak of war makes 
 its performance not impossible but extremely onerous for one of 
 the parties. (See under War as Force majeure, infra, p. 307.) 
 
 Effect of contracts as between the parties and as against third 
 
 parties. 
 
 In considering this subject it is necessary to distinguish con- 
 tracts of which the effect is to transfer property or real rights, 
 that is contracts which are at the 'same time conveyances, from 
 contracts which have not this effect. And it will be convenient 
 to divide the subject thus: (1) the effect of contracts in trans- 
 ferring property between the parties; (2) the effect of contracts 
 in transferring property in regard to third parties; and (3^ the 
 effect of non-translatory contracts with regard to third parties. 
 But before dealing with these questions there are certain pre- 
 liminary matters which have to be disposed of. We have to 
 determine to begin with who are the parties to a contract and 
 who are third parties. 
 
 LThe broad rule is laid down in the codes that contracts have 
 effect only between the contracting parties. They cannot pre- 
 judice third parties, nor can they benefit them except in cases 
 
12 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 specially provided for. (C. C. N. 141, 142: C. C. M. 202, 203. 
 See C. C. F. 1165; C. C. Q. 1023.) 
 
 This is the principle sometimes spoken of as that of the rela- 
 tivity of contracts. The articles in the Egyptian Code are as 
 follows: — 
 
 Agreements cannot enure to the benefit of third persons, other 
 than the creditors of the contracting party, who can, in virtue of 
 the general right which they have over the property of their 
 debtor, exercise, in the name of such debtor, all such rights of 
 action as accrue to him from contracts or from any other source 
 of obligation, save only such rights of action as are purely per- 
 sonal. (C. C. E. 141/202.) 
 
 Agreements cannot prejudice third persons, as against whom 
 they cannot be set up unless they have a legally established date. 
 (C. C. E. 142/203.) 
 
 With these articles may be conveniently considered the article 
 of the French Code which declares that a man cannot, in general, 
 bind anybody but himself by a contract, or bind another to a third 
 party by a contract. This is a free translation of the famous 
 rule, 
 
 On ne pent, en general, s 'engager, ni sti/puier en son propre norm, 
 que pour soi-meme. (C. C. F. 1119.) 
 
 This broad rule is qualified by the two articles which follow it 
 in the French Code, in which it is declared: (1) that a man can 
 guarantee that a third party shall do something, in this sens© 
 that the promisor binds himself to pay damages if the third party 
 will not take over the obligation; and (2) that a man may stipulate 
 for the benefit of a third party when this is a condition of a stipu- 
 lation which he makes for himself, or of a gift which he makes, 
 and that where he has made such a stipulation for the benefit of 
 a third party, and the third party has declared his intention of 
 taking advantage of it, the stipulation can no longer be revoked. 
 (C. C. F. 1120, 1121; C. C. Q. 1028, 1029. Cf. C. C. E. 
 137/198.) 
 
 But, as will be pointed out later, the rule that contracts cannot 
 affect third parties is subject to other exceptions. These two 
 cases which the French Code gives as exceptions to the rule, 
 namely, the contract se porter fort and the stipulation pour autrui, 
 will need to be considered when we have first examined what are 
 the effects of contracts between the parties and as regards third 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 13 
 
 parties, apart from these two particular cases which are specially 
 provided for. 
 
 r 
 
 Who are the parties to a contract? 
 
 The parties to a contract are, primarily, those who have per- 
 sonally consented to it. But other persons may be parties to the 
 contract although they did not appear in it by themselves. If 
 I give to a man authority to act as my agent, and, in the execution 
 of his functions as agent, he makes a contract in my name, I am 
 a party to the contract just as much as if I had given the consent 
 'myself. I have, in fact, given the consent myself, although I 
 have given it indirectly by authorising my agent to act for me 
 in the matter. Qui f/ctolt per alium facit per se. (Aubry et Eau, 
 4th ed. 4, p. 650; Cass. 5 juin 1898, D. 98. 1. 559; D. N. C. ('. 
 art. 1998, n. 1.) 
 
 Representation in contract. 
 When is an agent a party? 
 
 When my agent in making the contract declares that he is 
 acting in my behalf he does not bind himself personally at all. 
 Through his instrumentality I acquire a direct right of action 
 against the party with whom my agent made the contract, and 
 this party acquires a direct right of action against me, while the 
 agent himself drops out as soon as the contract is made. (Pothier, 
 Oblig. n. 87; B.-L. et Wahl, Contrats Aleatoires, n. 800.) 
 
 Nor does the ag^ent bind himself when he has exceeded the 
 authority which I gave him, if he gave the part}- with whom he 
 contracted a sufficient communication of his powers. (C. C. E. 
 524/643; C. C. F. 1997; C. C. Q. 1717; C. A. Alex. 19 fevr. 
 1903, B. L. J. XV, 155.) 
 
 If my agent shows to the other party the written authority 
 which I gave him, or explains the position in which he stands to 
 me, and that he is acting on my behalf, it is for the other party 
 to satisfy himself that the agent is acting within the limits of his 
 authority. He knows that the agent is not adting for himself, 
 and he knows, also, that the agent does not guarantee that he has 
 authority to make the contract, for by communicating the extent 
 of his authoritj*, the agent throws upon the other party the re- 
 sponsibility of judging whether he has power to make this parti- 
 cular contract. (B.-L. et Wahl, Control* Aleatoires, n. 806. A 
 
14 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 It is only when he exceeds his powers and does not disclose 
 the extent of his authority, that the agent binds himself personally, 
 for, in this case, he cannot be acting- as an agent, seeing that what 
 he does is outside the scope of the agency. 'C. A. Alex. 16 nov. 
 1905, B. L. J. XVIII, 15.) 
 
 Unless the principal chooses to ratify what the agent who 
 exceeds his authority has done, he is not a party to the contract , 
 or, perhaps a more correct way of expressing the law is to say that 
 the principal, although not a party to the contract when it is 
 made, if the agent exceeded his powers, is given by law the option 
 of coming into the contract afterwards. (C. C. E. 527/648; 
 C. C. F. 1998; C. C. Q. 1720; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 4,'p. 651; 
 B.-L. et Wahl, Controls Aleatoires, n. 785; C. A. Alex. 1 fevr. 
 1899, B. L. J. XI, 116.) 
 
 When an agent acts in his own name the situation is entirely 
 different. It may be, and generally is, perfectly well understood 
 that he is not contracting on his own behalf. 
 
 He is really an agent because he is doing business for another . 
 
 But by acting in his own name, he binds himself personally, 
 and becomes the direct debtor or creditor of the person with whom 
 he contracts, although he still is an agent vis-a-vis of the jjerson 
 on whose behalf he was acting. (B.-L. et Wahl, op. cit. nos. 880, 
 900; Cass. 3 mai 1893, D. 93. 1. 567; C. C. Q. 1716. See Code 
 Comm. E. 82/86; C. A. Alex. 3 mai 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 235.) 
 
 Factors and brokers. 
 
 Certain kinds of agents, such as factors — commissionnaires—or 
 brokers — courtiers — habitually act in this way. 
 
 Their principals are not named and do not appear in the trans- 
 action. 
 
 A commissionn-aire or an agent de change always and neces- 
 sarily acts as an intermediary. 
 
 He cannot, for example, sell his own goods to his clients unless 
 he discloses the fact that they are his. He cannot be the contre- 
 partie as well as the broker. Otherwise the client -can get the sale 
 annulled. (Req. 28 mars 1904, D. 1905. 1. 65; Lyon-Caen et 
 Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 3, n. 414; Manuel de Droit 
 Commercial, 11th ed. n. 480, and n. 828.) 
 
 Stockbrokers are subject to somewhat different rules from other 
 brokers. The courtier, according to Egyptian usage, may sell his 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 15 
 
 own shares to his client if ho sells them at the market-price. 
 (C. A. Alex. 24 jam. 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 101; C. A. Alex. 
 8 mail907, B. L. J. XIX, 239.) 
 
 The rule is that factors and brokers contract a* principals, and 
 the other party to the contract looks to the eommissionnairt alone 
 or the courtier. He has nothing to do with the person for whom 
 the commissionnaire is acting. 
 
 If I buy shares on the stock exchange through a stockbroker, 
 the ordinary course of business is for me to buy them from the 
 broker. 
 
 In order to get the shares for me the broker has to buy them 
 from somebody else, generally from another broker who is acting 
 for the actual holder of the shares. Between me and this actual 
 holder no contractual relation exists. I have an action against 
 the broker on my contract with him, and the shareholder who sells 
 his shares has an action against his own broker, while each of the 
 brokers has rights of action against his client and against the other 
 broker, but the new shareholder and the old shareholder have no 
 action against each other. (Authorities in preceding note; C. A. 
 Alex. 3 mai 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 235.) So much has been said 
 in order to explain that there are numerous cases in which a man 
 is a party to a contract, although he did not personally appear in 
 it. He is a party because he was represented in the contract by 
 his agent. 
 
 Involuntary representation. 
 
 Besides this representation to which he has consented there are, 
 however, cases in which a man becomes bound by a contract in 
 which he was represented, though, as a matter of fact, he did not 
 authorise the representation. These are the cases in which there 
 is what may be called an " involuntary representation," or a re- 
 presentation created by law and not by agreement. 
 
 So, the minor is bound by the contract which his tutor makes 
 on his behalf so long as the tutor is acting within his legal 
 authority . 
 
 So also, if a man does something for my benefit in such circum- 
 stances as to make him my negotioriom gestor, according to the 
 principles which will be explained more fully later, I become 
 bound by contracts into which my negotiorum gestor entered in 
 my name although I knew nothing about them. And the parties 
 with whom he dealt may, in certain circumstances, have a direct 
 
16 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 action against me. (Laurent, 20, n. 332; Dissertation of M. 
 Planiol, in note to I). 91. 1. 49; infra, p. 155.) 
 
 Or, to take an example from the commercial law, if a trader 
 has been declared insolvent, and a concordat or scheme of settlement 
 has been agreed to by the majority of the creditors, who repre- 
 sent moreover three-fourths of the debts, and this composition is 
 confirmed by the court, it becomes binding upon all the creditors, 
 even those who were not present at the meeting or those who were 
 present and opposed the scheme. (See C. Com. N. 328; C. Com. 
 M. 338; C. A. Alex. 8 mai 1895, B. L. J. VII, 247.) 
 
 For the law declares that the majority of the creditors, provided 
 certain other conditions are fulfilled, shall represent the minority. 
 This is another case of involuntary representation. 
 
 Summary. 
 
 The parties to a contract include therefore, in addition to those 
 consenting to it in person, (a) those who consented through an 
 agent; and (b) those whom the law binds to the contract because 
 it was made by their legal representatives. 
 
 Heirs and successors. 
 
 In most contracts, besides the parties originally entitled or 
 bound, there is a possibility of other persons becoming entitled or 
 bound afterwards, because they succeed to the rights or debts of 
 the original parties. 
 
 The presumption is that a person who stipulates for something 
 to be paid to him intends that it is to be paid to his heirs if 
 he dies before the contract is executed. 
 
 And, in like manner, there is a presumption that a man who 
 binds himself to make a payment intends that if he does not pay 
 it in his lifetime it is to be paid by his heirs. 
 
 As the French Code expresses it: On est cense avoir stipule 
 pour soi et pour ses heritiers et atjants^Qfluse, a moins que le 
 contraire ne soit exprime ou ne resulte de la nature de la conven- 
 tion. (C. C. F. 1122; C. C. Q. 1030. Cf. German Code, art. 
 1967.^ 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no article to this effect, but the law 
 is the same. The rule is that obligations transmit both actively 
 and passively, but there are certain exceptions to the rule. For 
 the present purpose it is sufficient to point out that the aycmts 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 17 
 
 cause who succeed to the rights of a party to a contract arc. not 
 to be considered as third parties. 
 
 This is not for the reason that they had any part in the contract 
 when it was made, but because they have stepped into the shoes 
 of those who made it. It would be absurd to say that the rule 
 that third parties could neither benefit nor be prejudiced by con- 
 tracts applied to the ayants cause. If I make a contract which 
 my heir has to fulfil, he is just as much prejudiced by it as if 
 he had made it himself. 
 
 It is not necessary here to discuss the nature and the extent of 
 the liability of heirs and whether, and in what cases, an heir can 
 be liable in excess of the amount to which he has succeeded, or to 
 refer to the difficulties of the Mohammedan law on this subject. 
 
 (See, on the last matter, VEgypte Contemporaine, 5, p. 14, 
 article by Abd El Hamid Bey Badawi.) 
 
 Under any system of law the heir cannot be a third party in 
 the sense under consideration. 
 
 Meaning of "ayants cause." 
 
 The term ayant cmi&e^ is a more convenient one than any 
 corresponding English expression. It is often translated by the 
 word " representative," but this word suggests too much the idea 
 of agency which is quite a different thing. 
 
 By ayant cause is meant for our present purpose a person who, 
 without having consented to a contract either personally or 
 through a representative, has succeeded to one of the parties to 
 the contract or to a person who had rights or liabilities under it, 
 or has acquired from another a right under the contract. 
 
 The person to whom the ayant cause succeeds and in whose 
 place he comes, or the person from whom he acquires the right is 
 called his author. 
 
 It would not be sufficient for the definition to say that the 
 ayant cause succeeds to one of the parties. This is so in the case 
 of succession to a deceased person when the heir of the creditor, 
 or of the debtor, as the case may be, succeeds to him. But it is 
 possible for a man to succeed as an ayant cause to a right or to 
 a liability under a contract although his author was not himself 
 a party to the contract. This may happen when there is an 
 assignment of a debt. 
 
 The original creditor may assign the debt, in which case the 
 assignee succeeds to him as a party, but if the assignee in his 
 
 W.— VOL. II. 2 
 
18 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 turn assigns the debt, the second assignee is the ay ant cause of 
 the first, but he does not succeed directly to either of the parties 
 to the debt. The person who acquires under a contract a right of 
 property, may be correctly said to succeed to the right of property 
 which his author had, but the person in whose favour a hypothec 
 is created does not succeed to his right, for it is created for the 
 first time by the contract. 
 
 But he is, none the less, the ayant cause of the owner who 
 creates the hypothec, because he derives his right from him. (See 
 B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 211.) 
 
 Universal and particular ayants cause. 
 
 Ayants cause are of two kinds, denoted in the French law by 
 the terms ayants cause a titre universel, and ayants cause a titre 
 particulier. 
 
 The first are those who succeed to the whole estate of the author, 
 or to an aliquot share of it, such as a half or a quarter. These 
 will, generally, be heirs of a deceased person, because people do not 
 as a rule transmit their estate, or an aliquot part of it, in this way 
 during their lifetime. 
 
 But a man's creditors are also, in a sense, ayants cause uni- 
 versels, because such rights as they have are over the whole patri- 
 mony of their debtor. The position of creditors is, however, 
 different from that of other ayants cause universels, and I shall 
 consider it separately. 
 
 The ayants cause a titre particulier are those who succeed to 
 their author in some particular right or acquire some particular 
 right from him. The buyer, for instance, succeeds the seller as 
 owner of the thing bought. A person to whom a thing is left as 
 a legacy succeeds the ancestor as owner of this particular thing. 
 The creditor in whose favour a hypothec is created acquires from 
 the debtor a special and determinate right against the property 
 hypothecated, and so on. (Planiol, 1, n. 303; B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 211; Bufnoir, Propriefe et Contrat, p. 753.) 
 
 Rule that obligations transmit to universal successors only. 
 
 The general rule is that it is only the ayants cause universels 
 who succeed to the rights or to the liabilities of their author, and 
 the presumption is that the ayants came of this class do succeed 
 to both the claims and the debts. There are cases, however, in 
 which the obligation does not pass even to them. For (a) the 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 19 
 
 contract may provide that the right <or the debt shall not transmit, 
 as if, in buying- a house, I stipulate for myself that I shall have 
 a delay of ten years to pay the price, but that on inv death, if 
 that occurs within the ten years, the price shall be instantly pay- 
 able by my heirs. 
 
 In this case if I had not expressly deprived my heirs of the, 
 delay, they would have succeeded to so much as remained of it at 
 my death, as being a right which was vested in me. 
 
 (b) The contract may be of such a nature that it cannot pass 
 to heirs, as where I stipulate for myself a right of usufruct. 
 
 Or, (c) the contract may be one which the law declares shall 
 terminate at the death of the parties. 
 
 Thus the French and Egyptian Codes declare that the contract 
 of lease and hire of work comes to an end by the death of the 
 workman, though the Code of Quebec, with greater reasonableness, 
 says that this shall only be so in cases wherein the skill and ability 
 of the workman were an inducement for making the contract, 
 and then only at the option of the other party . (C . C . E . 41 1/502 ; 
 C. C. F. 1795; C. C. Q. 1692; B.-L. et Barde, 1, nos. 214 
 seq.) 
 
 Particular representatives. 
 
 The general rule as to particular representatives, or, as they are 
 otherwise called, singular successors, is the opposite of that with 
 regard to universal representatives. Eights and debts do not pass 
 as a rule to ayants cause a titre particulier. 
 
 If I sell a house to you, that does not make you in any way- 
 liable for my debts, or entitle you to enforce claims due to me;. 
 But in a certain limited sense you succeed to my debts and claims, 
 namely, to such of them as before the sale affected the right of 
 property in the house. For instance, if before the sale I had. 
 granted to my neighbour a servitude of running his drain under 
 the backyard of my house, you take the house subject to that 
 servitude . 
 
 Or, conversely, if, before the sale to you, I had stipulated for 
 a servitude in favour of this house over my neighbour's land, you 
 will take it with the servitude attached to it. 
 
 Or again, if I possess an estate composed of several farms, and 
 I have a dispute with my neighbours concerning the property of 
 certain parcels of land, or concerning servitudes, and the dispute 
 is terminated by a contract of compromise, in which I admit the 
 right of my neighbours to some pieces of land, or to some servu- 
 
 2 (2) 
 
20 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 tildes, and, in return, I obtain from them an admission of my 
 rights as to other disputed points, and, thereafter, I sell the estate 
 to a third party, this third party takes the estate subject to the 
 terms of this compromise. 
 
 He can claim the rights for which I stipulated, and he is subject 
 to these real rights which I created. 
 
 But in all the preceding cases, as will be explained presently, 
 an innocent purchaser for value is protected by the rules as to 
 transcription. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 223; Planiol, 2, n. 1180; 
 C. A. Alex. 13 janv. 1908, B. L. J. XX, 58, and cases in 
 B. L. J. Table* Decennales, vo. Transcription.) 
 
 But these cases are only apparent exceptions to the rule that 
 rights and debts do not transmit to singular successors. It is 
 not because the singular successor as such succeeds to the claim or 
 to the debt, but it is because he takes the thing- transferred in the 
 condition in which his author had it. 
 
 The singular successor is not as such directly bound by the 
 personal obligations of his author, even when these obligations 
 were relative to the thing which forms the object of the trans- 
 ference. If, for example, an owner makes a contract with a man 
 to do certain work on his property, and he afterwards sells the 
 property, the buyer has nothing to do with the contract which 
 the seller made. (See Cass. 23 dec. 1891, D. 92. 1. 409; Cass. 
 
 21 mars 1894, D. 94. 1. 240; Cass. 16 nov. 1896, D. 97. 1. 483.) 
 Bui if before the sale, the seller had done something which 
 
 restricted or modified the right transferred, as where he has created 
 a real right over it, or he has made a compromise concerning it. 
 the successor takes the property so modified or restricted. This 
 is an application of the rule nemo plus juris transferre potest 
 quam-ipse habet. Even in this case, as regards property, or real 
 rights less than property, the practical application of the rule is 
 much restricted by the provisions which require transcription or 
 registration. 
 
 A particular successor by onerous title, whose own right has 
 been made real by transcription, is not subject to real rights 
 created by his author even before the sale unless these real rights 
 were transcribed before his. (C.C.N. 611—615; C. C. M. 737 
 —742; Loi du 23 mars 1855; Planiol, 1. n. 2619; Grandmoulin. 
 Suretes personnelles, etc., p. 249.) 
 
 But a particular successor by gratuitous title, such as a donee 
 
 . or legatee, is liable to find that property given or bequeathed to 
 
 him is subject to real rights created by his author in favour of 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 21 
 
 thud parties, although these third parties have not complied with 
 the law requiring transcription. 
 
 But, in order to be so preferred, the third parties must them- 
 selves have acquired by onerous title and by a title that had 
 acquired a dale certaine before the particular successor's right 
 w~as tranaoriBed. (C. C. E. 617/744. Sec C. A. Alex. 9 fevr. 
 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 117; C. C. Q. 2098; Grandmoulin, op. tit. 
 p. 255.) 
 
 For it is certainly more equitable that the person who wishes 
 to avoid a loss— cert at d,e damno evitando, as the old lawyei-s 
 said, should be preferred to one who seeks to realise a gain— certat 
 de lucro captando . 
 
 Under the French law it is disputed whether a donee is to be 
 assimilated in this respect to a legatee. Many writers contend 
 that under the terms of the French legislation a donee is entitled, 
 like a successor by onerous title, to set up the want of transcrip- 
 tion against third parties. (D. N. C. C. v. 4, p. 1741, n. 49, and 
 authorities cited; Colin et Capitant, 1, p. 952.) 
 
 But the Egyptian Codes make it clear that the donee and the 
 legatee are in the same position as far as this matter is concerned. 
 (C. C. E. 617/744.) 
 
 Neither of them can set up the default of transcription as 
 against the third parties above indicated. 
 
 Subject however to the limitations created by the law which 
 requires transcription of real rights in order to make them effectual 
 against third parties, among whom we must for this purpose 
 include a particular successor of the creator of the real rights, the 
 rule undoubtedly is that the particular successor takes the pro- 
 perty as it was in the possession of his author, that is subject to 
 rights which that author had created oyer it, and, on the other 
 hand, that he is entitled to claim rights over it for which his 
 author had stipulated. 
 
 Can we go a step forther? Undoubtedly we can. We must 
 assimilate to stipulations creating real rights which transmit pleno 
 jure to aymts cause a titre particular such stipulations, as, without 
 neating a real right, have produced, in the direct interest of the 
 thing transferred, rights which have become identified with this 
 thing in such a way that one may say they have become accessories 
 to it, or in a certain sense qualities of it. (Demolombe, 24, 
 nos. 283 and 284; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 223; Aubry et Rail, 
 . 5th ed. 2, p. 97; D. N. C. G. art. 1122, n. 94. See C. A. 
 Alex. 9 fevr. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 117.) 
 
22 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 So a person, to whom a debt is assigned which is secured by a 
 surety or by a hypothec, succeeds to these accessory rights which 
 pass with the debt to which they belong. (Authorities in pre- 
 ceding note.) 
 
 And upon this principle, it is held in France that when an 
 immoveable has been resold by the purchaser, the sub-purchaser 
 succeeds to the right to bring the action in guarantee or warranty 
 against the original vendor, even in the case when the sub-pur- 
 chaser, as a successor by gratuitous title, would not have had any 
 such recourse against his immediate author. (Aubry et Rau, 
 oth ed. 2, p. 98, and 5, p. 88.)' 
 
 The action in guarantee passes from purchaser to purchaser as 
 an accessory of the property sold. (B.-L. et Saignat. Vente, 
 n. 359; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 5, p. 88; D. Supp. vo. Vente, 
 n. 426; D. N. C. C. art. 1626, n. 306 seq.) 
 
 And the same principle applies in regard to the sub-purchaser 
 of moveables. (Cass. 12 nov. 1884, D. 85. 1. 357.) So, also, 
 the purchaser of a house is subrogated de plein droit in the recourse 
 which the vendor had against the architect and contractor if the 
 building perishes in whole or in part within ten years from its 
 completion, owing to defect in construction, or even to the un- 
 favourable nature of the ground. (B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 2, 
 nos. 3925 and 3958; Rennes, 9 avr. 1870, D. 72. 2. 110; C. C. E. 
 409 500; C. C. F. 1792; C. C. Q. 1688.) The jurisprudence 
 upon this point in Quebec is in the same sense. (McGuire v. 
 Fraser, 1908, R. J. Q. 17 K. B. 449. 40 Canadian Supreme 
 Court Reports, 577.) Contrast the curious French case in which 
 it was held that the successive owners of a picture are not bound 
 by a declaration of the original vendor as to its authorship, 
 '■ (Cass. 23 dec. 1891, D. 92. 1. 409.) 
 
 And, in France, it has been held that when the vendor of 
 business-premises binds himself in the contract of sale not to 
 carry on any business of the same kind in the same town, this 
 obligation can be enforced by a sub-purchaser of the business- 
 premises. Cette obligation prohibitive, se rattachant par sa 
 nature el son objet a V etablissement lui-meme,'le suit dans quelques 
 mains qxCil passe. (Paris, 21 fevr. 1900, D. 1900. 2. 476; D. 
 Svpp. vo. Industrie et Commerce, n. 118. Supra, 1. p. 169.) 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 23 
 
 Analogous rule in English law. 
 
 So, in England it is held that the benefit of a covenant by a 
 vendor of a business, or of the covenant of a servant who has been 
 engaged in the business, that he will not trade in competition 
 with the purchaser or employer, as the case may bo, is part of the 
 goodwill of the business and is assignable with it. (Jacoby v. 
 Whitmore, 1883, 49 Law Times, 335; Baines v. Geary, 1887, 
 35 Oh. D. 154, 56 L. J. Oh. 935; Bemwell v. Inns, 1857, 24 Beav. 
 307, 116 B. E. 131. See Encyc. of Laws of Eng. vo. Restraint 
 of Trade, p. 268.) 
 
 In such contracts it is not necessary that the stipulation should 
 be expressly in favour of assigns. This is inferred from its 
 character. 
 
 Leases. 
 
 Moreover, there is another important case where a singular 
 successor succeeds to an obligation entered into by his author. 
 This is when the owner sells an immoveable which is leased. 
 
 The purchaser is bound to respect the lease and cannot turn out 
 the lessee, unless the lease contained a special stipulation to the 
 effect that the owner can put an end to the lease if he sells tho 
 property . 
 
 But in the French and Egyptian law it will only be when the 
 lease had a date certaine anterior to the sale that it can be thus 
 opposed to the purchaser. (C. C. E. 389/474. See C. A. Alex. 
 9 mai 1902^ B. L. J. XII, 242.) The purchaser is a third party 
 as regards any lease which had not a fixed date before the acqui- 
 sition of the property by him. And a lease of more than nine 
 years can only be opposed to him for nine years, unless it was 
 transcribed. (C. C. E. 613/740.) 
 
 There are on this subject certain differences of detail in the 
 provisions of the codes which do not need to be considered here. 
 (C. C. E. 389/474; C. C. F. 1743; C. C. Q. 1663. Cf . German 
 Code, arts. 571, 579. See Grandmoulin, Contrats, p. 152; Halton, 
 2, 134; Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 767.) 
 
 Creditors. 
 
 We are concerned here only with the chirographic creditors, 
 that is, with ordinary creditors who have no special guarantee by 
 having a real right such as a pledge or a hypothec. The creditors 
 who have such a real right can never be affected by the subsequent 
 
24 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 contracts of their debtor. (Planiol, 2, n. "2318; Aubry ct Rail, 
 5th ed. 2, p. 102.) 
 
 But the chirographic creditors are in a different situation. 
 They are not strictly speaking the ay ant S cause of their debtor, 
 because they have not acquired any property from him, or suc- 
 ceeded him in any right, but they are in a situation similar in somo 
 respects to that of the ayants cause by virtue of the provision of 
 law that the property of a debtor is the common pledge of his 
 creditors. (C. C. F. 2093; C. C. Q. 1981. Of. C. C. E. 
 141/202.) They look for payment of their debt to the property 
 of their debtor if he will not pay .the debt voluntarily, but as they 
 have no real security, and as the debtor is left in the administra- 
 tion of his property, this property which forms their common 
 pledge is continually being modified by the acts of their debtor.. 
 If he acquires a new right this increases his assets, and the security 
 of his creditors becomes by so much the greater. 
 
 On the other hand, if he alienates anything, or becomes liable 
 for a new debt, their common pledge suffers a corresponding 
 diminution. It is therefore very manifest that the contracts made 
 by the debtor do in fact benefit or prejudice his creditors, and 
 that they are not to be regarded as among those third parties who 
 cannot be affected by a contract in which they had no part. Seeing 
 that the creditors are affected by the contracts of the debtor they 
 are frequently described as being among the ayants cause 
 universels. 
 
 We may say, if we like, that the debtor in making a contract 
 represents his creditors. We may speak of this as "constructive 
 representation " because there is no conscious representation. The 
 debtor does not regard himself as acting on behalf of the creditors, 
 but by operation of law his acts do affect them as if he represented 
 them! (Planiol, 1, n. 305; 2, n. 1174. See C. A. Alex. 11 nov. 
 1903, B. L. J. XVI, 7.) It is because the debtor represents his 
 creditors that when, to their prejudice, he refuses to exercise a 
 right which he has. they can claim to act for him, or in other 
 words, can avail themselves of the indirect action which will 
 be explained later. As he will not act for them they claim to 
 act for themselves. 
 
 But, though from this point of view, the chirographic creditors 
 are ayants cause of their debtor, this is only in the sense which 
 has been explained that they must endure the competition — subir 
 le concows — of other creditors, even of later date, so that they 
 may see their common pledge diminished by an alienation made 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 25 
 
 1)\ theii' debtor. But the creditors are not ayants cause in the 
 sense that they are ever bound personally and directly by the 
 obligations contracted by their debtor. (Bufnoir, Propriete et 
 Contrat, p. 766.) 
 
 Moreover, the chirographic creditors themselves are in certain 
 respects considered as third parties and are, in this character, 
 protected against the acts of their debtor. 
 
 It is only while the debtor is acting in good faith that he is 
 regarded by the law as representing his creditor. He may 
 squander his property and they will have no right to complain. 
 But it is otherwise if an insolvent debtor acts with the fraudulent 
 intention of diminishing the pledge of his creditors, for when he 
 acts in bad faith he ceases to represent them. The creditors can 
 in this case bring the direct action, otherwise called the Paulian 
 Action, to annul the contract which the debtor has made. 
 
 When they do this they are exercising a right which belongs 
 to them; they are in the position of third parties who claim they 
 cannot be affected by the contract. This action will be fully 
 explained later. So, we see that the creditors appear some- 
 times in the position of ayants cause universels who are affected 
 by the contracts of their debtor, and, on the other hand, they 
 appear sometimes as third parties who can challenge these con- 
 tracts. 
 
 (Planiol, 1, n. 305. See Cass. 29 oct. 1890, D. 91. 1. 475.) 
 
 Summary. 
 
 To sum up what has been said: (1) persons are not third parties 
 to a contract in the sense under discussion if they were repre- 
 sented in the contract by persons authorised to do so by the law. 
 (2) Further, the ayants cause universels of the contracting parties 
 are not third parties as to the contracts to which their author was 
 a party. (3) Ayants cause a titre particulier of the parties, such 
 as purchasers or donees from them, are not third parties as regards 
 contracts made by their author prior to the transference to them, 
 if such contracts augmented or diminished their author's rights 
 over the thing transferred, but they are third parties as to all 
 other contracts made by their author. (4) Lastly, chirographic 
 creditors are in a certain sense ayants cause universels and are, 
 therefore, affected by their author's contracts. But they have 
 special rights given to them by law for the protection of their 
 
26 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 interests, and when they are exercising these rights they may 
 properly be considered as third parties. 
 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 581; D. N. C. 0. art. 1165, nos. 9 seq.) 
 
 In the preceding cases we have been considering the case of 
 persons who are affected by a contract because they are not in a 
 legal sense third parties as far as this contract is concerned. 
 
 But besides these there are cases where persons who are un- 
 questionably .third parties to a contract may be affected by it, 
 nevertheless. 
 
 It is these cases which have now to be explained. 
 
 f i . ]ut 
 Exceptions to the rule that contracts do not benefit or 
 prejudice third parties. 
 
 The most important exception to the rule is the one expressly 
 made in the French Code. (C. C. F. 1165; C. C. Q. 1028.) 
 This is the case of the stipulation pour autrui, under which a, 
 person not a party to the contract, nevertheless, acquires a direct, 
 right under it. 
 
 This will be explained later. It may be remarked that the 
 Egyptian codes ought to have made this exception in the corre- 
 sponding article. (C. C. E. 141/202.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code expressly recognises the stipulation 
 pour autrui although in terms which are somewhat obscure, 
 (art. 137/198), and we must conclude that the broad rule, stated 
 in article 141/202, is intended to be subject to this exception. 
 But besides the stipulation pour autrui there are undoubtedly 
 other oases where a contract benefits or prejudices third parties. 
 
 (1) The rule that contracts do not affect third parties does not 
 apply except as to personal rights. 
 
 If the effect of the contract has been to transfer property or 
 real rights, the new owner of the property or the creditor in tho 
 real right can set up his right not only against his author but 
 against third parties, such as particular successors of his author. 
 
 It is of the very essence of the real rig-ht that its owner can 
 defend it against all comers. (Dcmolombe, 25, n. 45; B.-L. et 
 Chauveau, Biens, n. 246; Cass. 20 fevr. 1900, D. 1900. 1. 250; 
 Req. 21 mars 1894, D. 94. 1.240; D. N. C. Cart. 1165, n. 67.) 
 If moveables have been transferred to me by a contract the rule 
 possession vaut titre is, in most cases, enough to protect me 
 against any claims, and if I have acquired a real right over an 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTHACTS. 27 
 
 immoveable I am protected also against claims by third parties, 
 at least if I have satisfied the formalities which the law requires. 
 
 Protection given to third parties. 
 
 Under the law governing- transcription or registration of real 
 rights over immoveables, it may be that I enjoy this protection 
 only if I have registered my right before my opponent has got his 
 right registered. 
 
 The effect of publicity by means of transcription or inscription 
 in the register will be explained later. (C. C. E. 611/737; 
 C. C. Q. 2098; Loi du 23 mars 1855, D. 55. 4. 26.) 
 
 And, in any case, if I am to be allowed to set up my right 
 against third parties, I must be able to give it a legally ascer- 
 tained date which shows that my right is prior to theirs. 
 (C. C. E. 142/203; C. C. F. 1328. Cf. C. C. Q. 1225; Cass. 
 9 janv. 1901, D. 1901. 1. 449.) For instance, if I have bought 
 a Held from B and it turns out that B was a non-dominus and 
 that A was the owner, then, if A revindicates the field from me, 
 I maj' be entitled to defend myself by the plea of prescription. 
 
 But in order to be allowed to do so, I must have a deed of 
 sale which has a date certains. (See Planiol, 2, n. 74; Halton, 1, 
 p. 419.) By the laws which prescribe registration of real rights, 
 and refuse to allow a private writing to prove its own date, third 
 parties dealing in good faith are in most cases safe, but it 
 cannot be denied that in principle contracts which transfer 
 propert}' may affect third parties. 
 
 (2) Contracts which affect the status of the contracting parties, 
 or which regulate their property after a change of status, may 
 benefit or prejudice third parties. Thus the effect of marriage 
 may be, as it is in the French law, that the wife cannot make- 
 certain contracts without the authorisation of her husband, or the 
 contract of ma,rriage may give to the husband certain special rights 
 over the wife's property. 
 
 In either case, third parties may be affected by the change in 
 the wife's status, or by the rights given to the husband by the 
 marriage-contract, for example, the right of administration of the 
 property comprised in the community. (D. Rep. Oblig. n. 290; 
 Cass. 17 dec. 1873, D. 74. 1. 145; Beudant, Contrats, p. 572.) 
 
 (3) Again, the fact that two persons have entered into a part- 
 nership, seriously affects third parties who deal with them, and 
 this is why the law provides that a partnership agreement, or, at 
 
28 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 any rate, one which creates a commercial partnership, must be 
 published to the world in such a manner as to give third parties 
 sufficient notice of it if they are to be affected by it. (C. Comm. 
 E. 48/54; Lai du '24 juill. 18G7, arts. 55 — 61, abrogating C. 
 Comm. F. 42 seq. See Thaller, Traite EUm. cle Droit Commer- 
 cial, 4th ed. n. 359.) 
 
 (4) A contract in virtue of which a person enjoys a monopoly 
 affects third parties. 
 
 If the exclusive right to run tramcars within a certain area is 
 given to one company this affects possible competitors. (See Civ. 
 18 oct. 1910, D. 1912. 1. 233.) 
 
 (5) There is, further, considerable French authority for a pro- 
 position which greatly narrows the application of the general rule 
 that contracts affect only the parties to them. 
 
 This is that when the execution of a contract would have re- 
 sulted in a direct benefit to a third party, and the contract is 
 wilfully or fraudulently broken, the third party may sue the party 
 who has broken the contract for reparation of the loss caused to 
 him b}" the breach. 
 
 For example, A orders from B goods manufactured by C, and 
 B fraudulently supplies other goods; C has an action against B 
 for damages. 
 
 In several cases the wrong alleged was the substitution of one 
 brand of wine or liqueur in place of another one which was 
 ordered. 
 
 The claim is delictual, being founded on fault, but if the cases 
 are well decided, they strike a serious blow at the relativity of 
 contracts. 
 
 It will be observed that they do not fall under the principle of 
 the stipulation pour autrui, as there is ho intention on the part 
 of A to stipulate a benefit for C. 
 
 (Paris, 8 juin 1904, D. 1905. 2. 270; Heq. 30 dec. 1912, S. 
 1913. 1. 156; Rev. Trim. 1913, p, 622.) 
 
 (6) Moreover, although a third party cannot incur any con- 
 tractual liability from the breach of a contract to which he was 
 no party, yet nevertheless, if he conspires with one of the parties 
 to break the contract he will be liable in damages to the other 
 party to whom prejudice is thereby caused. 
 
 This is what is called la responsabiUte du tiers complice*, and, 
 like the last case, belongs to the law of responsibility. (Cass. 
 27 mai 1908. I). 1908. 1. 459; Nancy, 4 avril 1906, S. 1906. 2. 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 29 
 
 241; Ilev. Trim. 1912, p. 167. See Pierre Hugueney, Respon- 
 sabilite Civile du Tiers Complice, These, Dijon, 1910.) 
 
 (7) Another exception is that which is created by the rule that 
 novation by substitution of a new debtor can be made without 
 the consent of the first debtor. (C. C. E. 1ST 251; C. C. F. 
 1274; C. C. Q. 1172.) 
 
 (8) Lastly, the rule that the payment of a money debt may be 
 made by a third party instead of by the debtor is, in a sense, an 
 exception to the rule under discussion. 
 
 The third party has a right to come in and take the debtor's- 
 place, at least, for this important purpose. (C. C. E. 160/223; 
 0. C. P. 1236; C. C. Q. 1141; Bufnoir. Propriete et Contrat, 
 p. 752; infra, p. 445.) 
 
 In fact, when we consider all the various exceptions which have 
 to be made, it becomes clear that the scope of the rule is much 
 narrower than at first appears. 
 
 It does not follow that it is not an important rule. It is, 
 however, hardly necessary to furnish many examples of its 
 application. Two may be given. If one of two co-proprietors 
 contracts with a third party, the contract does not bind the other 
 co -proprietor. Again, the owner of land is not bound by contracts 
 made by the possessor. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 749.) 
 A labourer employed by a farmer on shares has no direct action 
 for his wages against the owner of the land. (Cass. 18 ocjt. 
 1898, D. 99. 1. 105. For other interesting illustrations, see 
 Cass. 8 aout 1883, D. 84. 1. 81; Paris, 21 oct. 1902, D. 1903. 
 2. 121; C. A. Alex. 18 mai 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 330.) 
 
 These illustrations may suffice. 
 
 Rule does not mean that contract may not be proved by 
 third parties as a fact. 
 
 The rule that agreements cannot affect third parties means that 
 third parties cannot acquire rights or incur liabilities under them. 
 It does not mean that a contract may not throw light upon the 
 rights of a third party. He does not claim that any right is given 
 to him by the contract to which he was not a party, but he claims 
 that the contract throws light upon his position, and that it may, 
 therefore, be proved as a fact in support of the case which he 
 submits to the court. Un contrat petit etre invoque dans une 
 contestation contre un tiers, a Vappui d'une affirmation de fait, 
 pour etahlir la situation exacte des parties oontractantes Vunc 
 
30 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 vis-a-vis de Vautre. (Cass. 3 fevr. 1879, D. 79. 1. 308; Cass. 
 27 juin 1892, D. 92. 1. 379.) 
 
 For example, take the case where a landowner, on whose property 
 there is a mine, has given to another the right to work the mine 
 subject to payment to him of a certain sum for every ton (or other 
 unit) extracted. The landowner, in other words, instead of 
 realising a fixed rent is to-be paid in the form of what is called 
 a "royalty." Now, if a railway company by placing its line 
 where it is, has restricted the working of the mine, and the question 
 is what compensation must be paid to the landowner, the proof 
 of the value of this royalty will naturally be found in the agree- 
 ments between him and the person who has the mining concession. 
 
 The contract which he made with this other person cannot give 
 the landowner a right against the railway company, but it may 
 materially help to show the extent of the loss caused to him by 
 the construction of their line. (Cass. 3 janv. 1853, D. 53. 1. 
 133.) 
 
 Translatory and non-translatory contracts. 
 
 Having now explained what we mean when we speak of the 
 parties to a contract, and who are meant by "third parties," we 
 are in a position to discuss the effect of contracts as between tha 
 parties in the first place, and in the second place as against third] 
 parties. 
 
 For this purpose it is necessary to distinguish between trans- 
 latory contracts and non-translatory contracts. 
 
 Effect of contracts in transferring property between the 
 
 parties. 
 
 This is dealt with in the French Code in a number of articles, 
 of which the most important are articles 938, 1138, and 1583. 
 (Cf. C. C. Q. 795, 1472, 1596.) In the Egyptian codes the 
 corresponding articles are as follows: — 
 
 An obligation to transfer a thing transfers ipso facto the 
 ownership thereof, when the thing in question is a specific cor- 
 poreal thing whereof the party bound is owner. 
 
 An obligation to create a real right iff like manner transfers 
 such right, except in the case of rights of privilege, hypothec 
 mid retention. (C. C. E. 91, 92/145, 146. Cf. C. C. E. 
 48/70; C. C. N- 357.) 
 
 The former of these articles is in the section devoted to the 
 obligation de donner, and it declares that this obligation makes 
 
 .♦Mr 
 
 ^ A/^ijJba*. 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 31 
 
 the creditor owner of the thing even before delivery. The phrase 
 obligation de donner is the consecrated expression in France for 
 an obligation the object of which is to effect transfer of properly. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 344; Planiol, 2, n. 159.) 
 
 It is bore a translation of the Latin word dare, which, in this' 
 technical sense, must be carefully distinguished from donare, as 
 it in no way implies the intention to make a gift. (Bufnoir, 
 Propriete et Contrat, p. 43; supra, I, p. 17.) 
 
 The same principle is laid down in the French Code in dealing 
 with the separate contracts by which property may be transferred, 
 such as gift, sale, and exchange. (C. C. F. 938, 1583, 1703.) 
 The Civil Code of Lower Canada states the same principle more 
 clearly in a general article: 
 
 .4 contract for the alienation of a thing certain and determinate 
 medics the purchaser owner of the thing by the consent (done of 
 the parties, although no deliver;/ be made. (C. C. Q. 1025.) 
 And it, likewise, contains articles of a corresponding kind in 
 dealing with the separate contracts. 
 
 The Egyptian Code makes it clearer than the other codes that 
 the obligation to constitute a real right is likewise translatory as 
 between the parties and their ayants cause. An obligation to 
 create a real right in like manner transfers such right, except in 
 the case of rights of privilege, hypothec, and retention. 
 (C. C. E. 92/146. See C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1905, B. L. J. 
 XVIII, 37, as to the effect of a promise to constitute a hypothec.) 
 Thus, for example, a right of usufruct, or a servitude, is created 
 as between the contracting parties by the contract itself. 
 (Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 40.) 
 
 The rule, that in a translatory contract the property passes at 
 once by the mere consent of the parties, is subject in the Egyptian 
 law and in the law of Quebec to an important exception. A 
 ship cannot be sold in whole or in part, except by a document 
 executed in a certain way, and a transfer which does not comply 
 with the prescribed forms does not convey any title to the pur- 
 chaser. (Code of Maritime Commerce, E. art. 3; C. C. Q. 2359, 
 2362.) 
 
 In France the particular form is required ad probationem, but 
 its absence does not make the contract null. (Code Comm. F. 
 195; Loi du 23 nov 1897; B.-L. et Saignat, Vente, n. 19; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1582, n. 225.) 
 
 It may be observed in passing that the French Code deals with 
 the question of the transfer of the risk in connection with the 
 
 
52 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 transfer of the property. The obligation to deliver the thing 
 rend le creancier propi'ietaire et met la chose a ses risques des 
 V instant oil elle a du etr.e livree, encore que la tradition nen ait 
 point etc. faite, a moins que le debiteur ne soit en demeure de la 
 Hirer. (C. C. F. 1138.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code does not treat of the risk in this place, but 
 does so in dealing with the law of sale, where, unfortunately, the 
 texts are very difficult to reconcile with one another. (Arts. 
 266/336 and 297/371.) 
 
 This is not the place to discuss this subject. (See Halton, 2, 
 p. 26; Grandmoulin, Contrats, p. 24. See infra, pp. 476 seq.) 
 
 The only point with which we are now concerned is the main 
 provision that the property in a res certa passes by the mere consent 
 of the parties to alienate it. 
 
 Roman law and old French law as to effect of contract to 
 
 transfer. 
 
 As a matter of theory, this is one of the most important changes 
 introduced by the modern law. It was a cardinal principle of 
 the Roman law that a contract could not transfer the right of 
 property; all that it could do was to give to the creditor a personal 
 right to enforce' the transfer. 
 
 In the earlier period of the law, there- were certain formal 
 methods of transferring property, viz., in jure cessio and man- 
 cipatio. But, in the later law, it had become a settled principle 
 that to effect a change of property there must be delivery of the 
 thing. 
 
 Traditionibus et usueapionibus dominia rerum, non nudis pactis 
 transjeruntur. (Code, 2. 3. 20; Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 293.) 
 
 The old French law retained this principle. As regards im- 
 moveables, however, actual delivery in course of time came to be 
 no longer required. Its place was taken by what was called 
 "fictitious delivery " — tradition feinte, or, sometimes, "legal de- 
 livery" — tradition de droit. (Argou, Institutions au Droit 
 Francais, 11th ed. 2, p. 197; Pothier, Vente, n. 313; Beaunr. 
 Droit Coutumier Francois, Las Contrats, pp. 141 seq.) 
 
 This fictitious delivery consisted of a clause in the contract hy 
 which the person conveying the property declared that he divested 
 himself of his possession and gave delivery to the other party. 
 It was called the clause of dessaisine-saisine or vest et devest. 
 
 It usually ran thus: (the seller) s 'en est dessaisi et devest a et 
 en a smsi et vestu le dit . 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. . 38 
 
 (Viollet, Hist, du Droit Fr«w^«,2nded. p. (J09; Argou, I. c.) 
 As regards moveables the old French law si ill required actual 
 delivery. - 
 
 Modern French law. 
 
 This necessity was abolished by the Code Napoleon which placed 
 moveables and immoveables on the same footing in this respect . 
 
 Delivery, either fictitious or actual, was no longer required as 
 a pre-requisite to the passing of the property. The article of 
 the French Code intended to introduce this change is obscurely 
 expressed, and there are certain difficulties as to its interpretation 
 with which we do not need to concern ourselves. The Egyptian 
 Code is quite clear, and it merely gives effect to what the French 
 Code, in all probability, meant to say. (See Colmet de Santerre, 
 5, n. 55, bis, III; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 366.) 
 
 As a matter of abstract theory, the rule that consent passes the 
 property is an important innovation. But from the practical 
 point of view it makes much less difference than might at first be 
 supposed, when we are considering the effect of the contract as 
 between the parties only. When third parties are concerned, how- 
 ever, there is no doubt that the change is important. 
 
 Its importance has, notwithstanding, been exaggerated by some 
 writers, such as Larombiere, who says that the Civil Code has 
 nowhere else introduced a change so grave or so fruitful in con- 
 sequences (art. 1138, n. 3). 
 
 Other writers go to the opposite extreme. M. Bonnier says, 
 " The new principle is one of those superfetations, one of those 
 puerile subtleties— idola fori— which ought to be banished from 
 serious legislation.'" (Cited by Hue, 7, n. 98.) 
 
 The truth lies between these extreme views. The old law reso- 
 lutely refused to regard a man as owner till he had got possession. 
 But this was chiefly in order to protect, third parties who dealt 
 with the actual possessor in the belief that he was the owner. 
 The modern law protects them also, but in a different way, viz., 
 by requiring registration in the case of immoveables, and by the 
 rule possession vaut titre in the case of moveables. The great 
 "purpose of the law has been to protect innocent third parties from 
 the risks to which they would be exposed by transfers of property 
 without their knowledge. It is impossible to deal safely with 
 immoveables if buyers and lenders cannot rely upon tho public 
 registers, and they must be protected against changes of owner- 
 
 W. — VOL. II. «* 
 
34 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ship which do nut appear there. This is the main object of 
 modern systems of registration. 
 
 And, in regard to moveables, as to which it would be impossible 
 to require registration in order to give notice of change of owner- 
 ship, the innocent third party is protected by the rule possession 
 vaut litre. He can deal with the man who is in possession of the 
 moveables without enquiring how he got them. 
 
 [f he acquires the moveables from him by a just title and in 
 good faith, or if he takes them as a pledge in good faith, and lends 
 money upon them in the ordinary way of business, he will be 
 protected. (C. C. E. 46/68, 87/116; C. C. F. 2279, 2280. See 
 C. A. Alex. 17 avr. 1900, B. L. J. XII, 213.) 
 
 Even when the moveables have been stolen or lost the honest 
 buyer is protected if he buys from a dealer in similar articles, or 
 in a public market. 
 
 If the owner revindicates such things the buyer can recover 
 what he paid for them. 
 
 But when we are concerned with the parties themselves, there 
 is no reason why their agreement to transfer the property should 
 not produce, its full effect at once without requiring delivery or 
 any other external act. 
 
 Two conditions of rule. 
 
 The rule that the mere consent of the parties to a translator^ 
 contract passes the property is subject to two conditions: (1) that 
 the transferor is the owner of the thing to be transferred; and 
 (2) that the thing to be transferred is determinate. 
 
 (1) The Egyptian Codes, speaking of sale, say: The sale of 
 a determinate object which is not the property of the vendor is 
 invalid (art. 264 333. Cf. C. C. F. 1599; C. C. Q. 1487.) 
 
 In the ease of the sale of a thing belonging to another, the 
 disti net ion between sale as a contract creating obligations and 
 sale as a conveyance effecting an immediate transfer of property 
 becomes of great importance. 
 
 Although a man cannot sell what does not belong to him with 
 the effect of making the buyer at once the owner of the thing sold, 
 it is perfectly possible, and very common, for a man to sell a' 
 thing which is not his, with the understanding that he is to procure 
 it and then to transfer it to the buyer. 
 
 If the buyer and the seller both understand that this is what 
 they are doing, there is a valid contract in such a case, although 
 there is not, nor cannot be, an instantaneous change of property. 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 35 
 
 Strictly speaking, it is not a contract of sale according to the 
 definition of the Egyptian Codes. 
 
 It is an innominate contract, because the Egyptian Codes con- 
 fine the term " sale " to the translatory contract. But it is in fact 
 a sale in the sense of the Roman law and that of the old French 
 law. 
 
 The contract of sale in the Roman law was not translatory. 
 
 It was a contract which bound the vendor to deliver, and to 
 warrant, &c, and bound the purchaser to pay the price. (See 
 Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 535; Grandmoulin, Cmitrats, n. 42; 
 De Hults, V ente, n. 16.) 
 
 Such a contract is of the commonest at the present day . 
 
 It occurs, for example, when a man sells shares which he does 
 not own, or when a retail dealer sells goods which he has to procure 
 from a wholesale dealer or from a manufacturer. 
 
 (2) Unless the thing is a res certa there can be no instan- 
 taneous transfer of the property. 
 
 The question as to what is a determinate thing has already 
 been discussed in speaking of the object of contracts, and the full 
 discussion of it, as well as of the rule that the seller must be the 
 owner, belongs to the law of sale. 
 
 (C. A. Alex. 2 dec. 1903, B. L. J. XVI, 27; C. A. Alex. 23 
 mars 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 167; C. A. Alex. 28 fevr. 1912, 
 B. L. J. XXIV, 166. Supra, I, pp. 73 seq.) 
 
 Rule that property passes at once is not law of public order. 
 
 Although the natural effect of sale under the modem law is to 
 pass the property at once, this is not one of the essentials of the 
 contract. It may be stipulated that the property is not to pass 
 until some future time, or such a stipulation may be implied from 
 the circumstances. If a man gives a commission for the paint- 
 ing of a picture, or for the building of a machine, the time at 
 which the property is to pass will depend upon the intention of 
 the parties. 
 
 In general, the intention will be that the property is not to 
 pass till the thing has been completed and has been accepted by 
 the buyer. And the fact that instalments of the price have been 
 paid does not indicate that the property has passed to the buyer. 
 (Guillouard, Vente, I, n. 35; Cass. 14 mars 1900, D. 1900. 1. 
 497; Cass. 16 mai 1876, D. 78. 1. 97.) 
 
 3 (2) 
 
 ■"S 
 
 
36 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The English law is the same. It is a question of interpretation. 
 The fact that instalments of the price are to be paid at certain 
 specified periods of construction does not in itself imply that the 
 property in ihe completed part passes to the purchaser. 
 
 (Laing & Sons, Ltd. v. Barclay, Curie & Co., 1908, A. C. 
 35, 77 L. J. P. C. 33; Benjamin on Sale, 5th ed. pp. 358, 363; 
 Williston on Sales of Goods, s. 275.) 
 
 And one common form of sale is that in which the price of the 
 article is paid by instalments, and the buyer is not to become the 
 owner of the thing until all the instalments are paid. (D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1583, nos. 37 seq.) 
 
 In France the legality of this clause is disputed. (Thaller, 
 Traite Elem. de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. n. 1947.) But the 
 French jurisprudence is in favour of the legality, and it is for 
 the court to decide whether the particular contract is a sale or a 
 lease. (Cass. 22 dec. 1909, D. 1910. 1. 63; Req. 29 janv. 1902, 
 S. 1902. 1. 168; Rouen, 17 juin 1911, D. 1912. 2. 149; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1582, nos. 21 seq.; Hardouin, Vente a temperament, 
 these.) 
 
 The German Code authorises it (art. 455). 
 
 Its legality is admitted in England. (Helby v. Matthews, 
 1895, A. C. 471, 64 L. J. Q. B. 465; Benjamin on Sale, 5th ed. 
 ' p. 327.) 
 
 There is no doubt in the Egyptian law that the clause is lawful. 
 (C. A. Alex. 3 nov. 1910, B. L. J. XXIII, 4; C. A. Alex. 
 30 avril 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 350; Gaz. Trib. Ill, p. 160; 
 C. A. 27 juin 1916, Gaz. Trib. VI, p. 183; Trib, Comm. Alex. 
 15 dec. 1913, Gaz. Trib. IV, p. 41; Trib. Somm. Caire, 31 
 oct. 1916, Gaz. Trib. VII, p. 8. Same rule in Quebec, Banque 
 d'Hochelaga v. Waterous Engine Co., 1877,27 Canadian Supreme 
 Court Reports, 406, R. J. Q. 5 Q. B. 125.) 
 
 Contracts of this kind are becoming very common, both in 
 regard to immoveables and to moveables, and they no doubt present 
 certain clangers to creditors, and also tend to encourage people 
 J.o bur things when they have not the money to pay for them. 
 In Franco there has been much abuse of this method in offering 
 shares and stocks to buyers who were only to become owners of 
 them after they had paid the instalments in full. Sales of this 
 kind are called ventes a temperament, and by the loi du 12 mats 
 1900, an attempt is made to prevent the abuse of this method of 
 sale. (See Lyon-Caen et Renault, Manuel, 11th ed. n. 847, bis.) 
 
 Another common form of such a sale is that in which it is 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 37 
 
 onmhi np.fi with leas e. It is sometimes called location-vent e, and 
 sometimes, perhaps more correctly, it is described as a contrat 
 innommc. (See Trib. Somm. Alex. 28 mars 1914, Gaz. Trib.* 
 IV, p. 127.) 
 
 A moveable article, such as an automobile or a piano, is trans- 
 ferred, subject to the condition that the transferee is to pay so much 
 a month for the use of the article for a certain period, and when 
 the prescribed number of monthly payments have been made he is 
 to become the owner of the article. The monthly payments here 
 may be regarded as partly instalments of price. 
 
 The parties may call it a lease, but if the court considers that 
 it has the characteristics of a sale, they will give effect to the 
 intention of the parties. (Cass. 22 dec. 1909, D. 1910. 1. (53; 
 Rouen, 17 juin 1911, D. 1912. 2. 149.) 
 
 It is evident that such contracts are apt to deceive creditors. - 
 They may believe that the automobile or the piano belongs to 
 their debtor, and may give credit to him on the strength of his 
 being the owner. 
 
 On thi& account some French authorities hold that such a form 
 of sah) is null as contrary to public policy. (Thaller, I.e.) 
 
 But the validity of these sales is, as we have seen, recognised 
 by the jurisprudence in France, England, Quebec and Egypt, and 
 it seems too late to maintain that they should be considered as 
 null in principle, though stipulations of this kind will be inter- 
 preted strictly. (Trib. Civ. Cairo, 2 mai 1916, Gaz. Trib. VI, 
 p. 183.) 
 
 Moreover, the very frequency of such contracts largely pre- 
 vents their being a trap for creditors. 
 
 Before people give credit to a debtor on the strength of his 
 possession of an automobile or a piano, they have learnt by experi- 
 ence to enquire upon what terms he holds it. 
 
 In some of the American States such sales must be registered 
 to give notice to the public of the seller's title. (See Willi ston, 
 Sales of Goods, s. 327.^; .,,.- 
 
 Effect of contracts in transferring property as regards 
 third parties. 
 
 The Code Napoleon contained almost nothing on this subject. 
 The French law now rests upon the Joi du23 Mars 1855. 
 
 (See B.-L. et Barde. 1, n. 374. Of. C. C. E. 611 737; C. C. Q. 
 1027.) 
 
38 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 By the Roman law, ai we have seen, the property did not pass 
 even as between the parties without actual delivery, and, there- 
 fore, a fortiori it did not pass as against third parties. 
 
 This system had some great advantages: — 
 
 (1) The creditors could rely on the property in the possession of 
 their debtor being available for the satisfaction of their claims. 
 So long as it remained in the debtor's hands they oould seize it. 
 They were not liable to find that the debtor had alienated his 
 property though he remained in possession of it. 
 
 (2) A purchaser who obtained delivery was safe. He could 
 not be evicted by another purchaser who produced a prior title. 
 (Code, 2. 3. 20; Inst. 2. 1. 41.) 
 
 \m the old French law, as regards immoveables, the clause of 
 dixsaisine-saisine effected transfer both as between the parties and 
 as against third parties. (Supra, p. 32; Pothier, Vente, n. 321.) 
 
 Where there were two purchasers that one was preferred whose 
 title was prior to the other, provided that this title had a certain 
 date. (76.) But some of the coutumes in France required an 
 investiture or formal taking of saisine, or possession, and a record 
 of this investiture was registered. 
 
 The hi du 20—27 septembre 1790 abolished the necessity for 
 this formal taking of saisine, and provided that registration of 
 the title should have the same effect. 
 
 This law applied only to the provinces in which investiture had 
 been required. 
 
 But the advantages of the system of registration having been 
 demonstrated, the law was extended to the whole of France by the 
 law of 11 brumaire <k Van VII. (Viollet, Hist, dm Droit Civ. 
 Francais, pp. 608 seq.; Beaune, Droit Coutumier, Les Contrats, 
 pp. 152—159; B.-L. et Barde, 1, nos. 368 seq.) 
 
 Under this law, of two successive purchasers of an immoveable, 
 that one is to be preferred whose title is first registered. As 
 between the parties the clause of dessaisine-saisme was enough 
 to transfer the property. 
 
 But this was not to be allowed to prejudice a later purchaser 
 whose title was registered before the other. 
 
 The compilers of the Code Napoleon, after much hesitation 
 and difference of opinion, abolished this law, and introduced the 
 broad rule that consent transfers property even as against third 
 parlies. (B.-L. et Barde, 1. n. 372; Hue. 7, n. 121.) This 
 opened a wide door to fraud. A purchaser of an immoveable or a 
 

 EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 39 
 
 lender upon hypothec, could never be sure that he -would not be 
 
 c\ icted by some one who appeared with a prior title. 
 
 The loi du 23 mars 1855, returned to the system of the lc*i du 
 
 11 brumaire de Van VII, and the Codes of Egypt and of Quebec) 
 
 are, as to this matter, based upon the lot du 23 mars 1855.. 
 
 (C. ('. E. 611/737; C. C. Q. 2098 sea. ; Grandmoulin, Suretes 
 
 personnelles, n. 835.) The purchaser of an immoveable must 
 
 now register his right before he is secured in it . 
 
 According to one view in France, until the purchaser has regis- 
 . . . 
 
 tered his title he has no security that the property will not be 
 
 seized by the creditors of the seller. ' In a question with third 
 
 parties, registration is made an essential element of the contract 
 
 of sale. As to third parties, the seller remains the proprietor ^>-o j 
 
 until the registration of the deed of sale, and, consequently, his 
 
 creditors may validly seize the immoveable as the property of 
 
 their debtor. But this opinion does not appear to be sound. 
 ... 
 The creditors are not third parties who have real rights over . . 
 
 the immoveable. It is this second view which has been followed 
 
 in Egypt. The details cannot be discussed in this place. (See t 
 
 C. A.' Alex. 16 juin 1910, B. L. J. XXII, 368; Grandmoulin/ 
 
 Suretes, dc. n. 874; Bufnoir, Propriete et Cmtrat, p. 113; D. N. 
 
 C. C. 4, p. 1742, n. 60.) 
 
 But there is no doubt that a purchaser who has not registered his 
 title may be evicted by a subsequent purchaser from the same 
 vendor whose title gets on the register before his. In like manner, 
 a purchaser who has not registered his title may have to suffer the 
 burden of hypothecs or other real rights agreed to by his author 
 after the alienation to him, but registered before it. So long as 
 both sales are unregistered the earlier in date has the preference. 
 (C. A. Alex. 23 mai 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 354. Cf. C. A. 
 Alex. 23 mars 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 235.) 
 
 Exceptions to the rule that the real right first registered is y 
 
 preferred. x> { 
 
 (1) It is only a purchaser by onerous title, and when we say a 
 purchaser we mean the acquirer of a real right as well as a pur- 
 chaser of property, who can secure his right by getting it regis- .>\^t.j 
 tered, and is preferred to a purchaser of earlier date whose right is 
 not registered. When the conflict is between a purchaser by 
 onerous title whose right is not registered and a subsequent pur- 
 
40 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 chaser by gratuitous title whose right is registered, the purchaser 
 by gratuitous title will have to give way, though, according to the 
 Egyptian law, this will be so only when the title of the first 
 ' purchaser had acquired a date certaine before the transcription 
 made bv the purchaser by gratuitous title. (C. C. E. 617/744 ; 
 C. A. Alex. 21 mai 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 303. Cf. 0. C. Q. 
 2098.) In France, according to the prevailing view, a donee 
 whose right is registered enjoys the same preference as a purchaser 
 by onerous title. (D. N. C. C. vol. 4, p. 1741, n. 49.) 
 
 But this is not so by the Egyptian law, which in this respect is 
 much more equitable than the French law. And the law of 
 Quebec agrees with the Egyptian law. 
 
 (2) In order to avail himself of the preference given by first 
 registration, it is certainly essential that the second purchaser shall 
 not have acquired his right by a fraudulent agreement entered 
 into between him and the vendor in order to defeat the right of 
 the. first purchaser — fraus omnia rwmpit. The Court of Cassation 
 founds its decision to this effect on the general idea that fraud 1 
 X creates an exception to all rules, and that the law of 1855 was 
 • not intended to provide a convenient means for cheating innocent 
 third parties. (Cass. 27 nov. 1893, D. 94. 1. 343; Cass. 21 
 juill. 1885, S. 1887 1. 175; Pand. Frang. vo. Transcription, 
 u. 944. Contra, Mourlon, Transcription, 2, n. 453.) 
 
 The same result is reached by some of the writers by another 
 method . 
 
 The second purchaser has caused damage to the first purchaser 
 by his fault, and is, therefore, liable to make reparation on the 
 general principle of responsibility for fault . If the property which 
 he lias wrongfully acquired is still in his hands the restitution of 
 ' it to the first purchaser will be the appropriate reparation. It 
 only came into his hands by fraud, and lie receives the property 
 subject to the duty of restoring it. (Lyon -Caen in note to S. 94. 
 1. 343; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 396; C. A. Alex. 12 fevrier 1908, 
 B. L. J. XX, 89.) But does the mere knowledge by the second 
 purchaser that the seller to him had already alienated the pro- 
 perty to another, or had agreed to the constitution of a real right 
 over it, without any fraudulent collusion with him, prevent his 
 acquiring the property if his title is first ' registered ? This is a 
 disputed question in France, but it is generally answered in the 
 nes-ative. Neither the toi du 23 mars 1855 nor the Civil Code of 
 Lower Canad,. says that the second purchaser needs to be in good 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 4t 
 
 , faith in order to have his title preferred. C. C. Q. 2080, 2098.) 
 (The French Code, in dealing with deeds by which a gift is made 
 to a person — the greve— subject to a charge of restoring it at his 
 death to a substitute — the appele— prescribes that the deed must 
 be registered to have effect against creditors or third parties; and 
 it goes on to say that these third parties may plead the want «f 
 registration, although they may have had knowledge of the gift. 
 (C. C. F. 1071.) 
 
 Their private knowledge is not to be equivalent to the official 
 intimation, made to them by registration^ According to the pre- 
 vailing view in France, the principle here laid down applies also 
 to the case under consideration. (Authorities in preceding note; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 2, p. 459; Mourlon, Transcription, 2, 
 n. 452; Pandectes Frrnigaises, vo. Transcription, n. 939; and 
 D. N. C. C. 4, p. 1744, n. 121.) It is true that the law of 
 registration is devised to protect the interests of third parties in 
 good faith, but in order to secure this protection a general scheme 
 has been framed which in fact protects all those who in dealing- 
 wit h the transferor find that the forms have not been complied 
 with. In order to make the law effective it has to be general, and. 
 being general, it may occasionally benefit a person not specialh" 
 intended to be covered. -And it may, further, be argued that a 
 third party who has mere private knowledge is not really in bad 
 faith. The law says to him, " You are not bound to know of any 
 alienation which is not registered." (See Eevue Pratique, 31, 
 p. 244; Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 122.) 
 
 Whether the last argument is sound or not, there is nothing in 
 the French loi du 23 mars 1855 to prevent the second purchaser 
 of the immoveable, who has private knowledge of a prior aliena- 
 tion which has not been registered, from registering his own title. 
 and then founding on the want of registration by the first pur- 
 chaser. 
 
 Such a second purchaser can hardly be described as being " in 
 good faith," but he has complied with the provisions of the law, 
 and the benefit given by the law to the owner whose title is first 
 registered is not restricted to owners who acquire in good faith. 
 
 The language of the Egyptian Code is different. According 
 to that code it is only as regards third persona irh<> hare aeted 
 in good faith, laho have a just title and who have proiechd their 
 rights by observing the forms prescribed' by lair, that the o\\ 
 ship is transferred by transcription. (270/341.) 
 
 IHT- 
 
42 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 A proposal to alter the Egyptian law on this point and to 
 bring it into conformity with the French law, was made in the 
 course of the discussion as to the institution of Litres Fonciers 
 in Egypt. 
 
 A clause was proposed: Le simple connaissance de V existence 
 cCun acte portant sur un des droits mentionnes aux arts. 14 et 15 
 ne suffit pax pour constituer les tiers en mauvaise foi. But this 
 clause was struck out by the majority and does not appear in 
 the report of the commission. {Rapport du Comite de la Com- 
 mission Internationale de 1904 sur les Livres Fonciers, p. 17, 
 and p. 14 of the Rapport de la Sous-Commission.) The difficulty 
 of maintaining that a person who has acquired an immoveable 
 knowing that his author had previously sold it to another can be 
 held to have acted in good faith is insuperable. But in spite 
 of this the jurisprudence has fluctuated in an extraordinary 
 manner. 
 
 During the first period the Mixed Court of Appeals held that 
 " o'ood faith'' meant here the absence of simulation; mere know- 
 ledge of a prior alienation would not create bad faith. Qu'anx* 
 termes de Varticle 341 du Code Civil, le creancier qui oppose le 
 defaut de transcription doit etre de bonne foi, metis en ce sens que 
 son litre doit etre sincere et non pas en ce sens qu'il doit avoir 
 ignore V alienation de Vimmeuble. (C. A. Alex. 30 avr. 1890. 
 B. L. J. II, 406. In same sense, C. A. Alex. 19 fevr. 1896, 
 B. L. J. VIII, 121: C. A. Alex. 12 janv. 1898, B. L. J. X, 95.) 
 In 1903 begins a second period during which the jurisprudence 
 gives to good faith its natural interpretation: Qu'evid eminent 
 la bonne foi doit s 'entendre non dans le sens de la fraude qui 
 donne lieu a V action paulienne, mais, conformement an sens stride 
 des termes, du simple fait que le second acquereur connaissait 
 V existence de la premiere vente. 
 
 Que cette interpretation, deja admise ailleurs legislativeimnt 
 sous Vempire d'une legislation prevoijant li V absence du fraude" 
 (Laurent, XXIX. n. 191), doit etre rationnellement et a fortiori 
 admise sous Vempire du texte plus large de la legislation egyp- 
 tienne. (C. A. Alex. 24 nov. 1903, B. L. J\ XVII, 25.) 
 
 During a third period the jurisprudence frankly follows the 
 French law, and considers that the second purchaser cannot be in 
 bad faith unless there had been a concert frauduleux between him 
 and the vendor.' (C. A. Alex. 12 fevr. 1908, B. L. J. XX, 89. 
 In same sense. C. A. Alex. 23 mai 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 354; 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 43 
 
 C. A. Alex. 6 mai 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 365; ('. A. Alex. 23 
 avr. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 342; C. A. Alex. 2 dec. 1914, 
 B. L. J. XXVII, 42; C. A. Alex. 17 dec. 1914, B. L. J. XXVII, 
 68; C. A. Alex. 8 fevr. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 205.) 
 
 But during this period the jurisprudence is not uniform, and 
 there are cases in which mere knowledge of the prior alienation 
 has been considered to constitute bad faith. (C. A. Alex. 27 avr. 
 1915, Gaz. Trib. V, n. 336, p. 129; C. A. Alex. 24 avr. 1917, 
 Gaz. Trib. VII, n. 370, p. 123; C. A. Alex. 4 juin 1918, Gaz. 
 Trib. VIII, p. 296.) 
 
 Finally a fourth period has begun with the decision of 18 
 janv. 1919 (R. G. 581^3 A. J. ;, in which the Court of Appeal 
 returns to the view that mere knowledge of a prior alienation puts 
 the second purchaser in bad faith. This result is criticised severely 
 by a recent writer to whose analysis of the jurisprudence I am 
 indebted. From the legislative point of view there is much to 
 be said for not requiring that the purchaser should not be in good 
 faith*. But as the Egyptian codes now stand, it seems to me 
 impossible to arrive at this conclusion in spite of the learned 
 argument of this writer. (See De L'influence de la Mauvaisi 
 Foi en mature de Transcription, par M. Stair os Cademenos* 
 L'Egypte Contcmponune, 1919, p. 388.) 
 
 Effect of alienation of corporeal moveables as against 
 third parties. 
 
 It would obviously be impossible to preserve by registration 
 evidence of the ownership of moveables. Moveables have no fixed 
 situation, and their owner can remove them from one place to 
 another or from one country to another. Moreover, the interest 
 of commerce requires that the circulation of moveables shall be as 
 easy and rapid as possible, and to require formalities for their 
 transfer would render business impracticable. Accordingly, the 
 rule in regard to them is that a contract for their alienation trans- 
 fers the property as regards third parties as well as against the 
 parties themselves. If I sell my horse to A, and, afterwards, I 
 sell it over again to B, the second sale will carry nothing to B, for 
 A has already become the owner of the horse. But, although 
 the mere contract to transfer a moveable makes the transferee 
 the owner of it, a transferee who has not obtained the possession 
 is in a very insecure position on account of the operation of another 
 rule of the law. This is the fundamental rule— en fait de meubles 
 
 
44 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 la possession Witt Hire (C. C. F. 2279.; The Egyptian Code 
 and the Code of Quebec create a presumption of lawful title and 
 of good faith in favour of the possessor of the moveables. (C. E. 
 608/734; C. C. Q. 2268.) 
 
 The French law is really the same, for, although the French 
 Code says that possession is equivalent to title, its interpretation 
 has always been in accordance with the traditional view that if 
 the possession is proved to have "begun in bad faith the title fails. 
 La regie " en fait de meubles possession vaut litre " ne p-otege 
 (jae In possession aninio domini, et nan mile qui est precaire ou 
 dont Vorigine est equivoque ou obscure. Cette regie ne peut etre 
 invoquee que par le tiers acquereur ou possesseur de bonne foi. 
 (Nancy, 30 dec. 1891, D. 92. 2. 441. The full discussion of 
 this subject belongs to the law of property. (B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 871; Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, 
 p. 343; Aubry et Bau, 5th ed. 2, p. 143; D. N. C. C. art. 2279, 
 nos. 54 seq.; Req. ler fevr. 1893, D. 94. 1. 278; Beq. 22 mai 
 1906, D. 1906. 1. 351: De Hults, vo. Possession, nos. 41 seq.; 
 Halton, 1, p. 216.) 
 
 The theoretical justification of* the rule is not very easy, and 
 there has been a long controversy about it, but the practical con- 
 siderations in its favour are overwhelming . There would be no 
 security for commerce, if the purchaser in good faith of a corporeal 
 moveable who obtained possession of it was liable to be evicted 
 by some one with a prior title. An honest buyer who obtains 
 delivery ought to know that he is safe. 
 
 The necessities of commerce have also led to the extension of 
 this rule to negotiable instruments payable to bearer, such as 
 bank-notes, promissory notes, and the like. These arc, strictly 
 speaking, incorporeal moveables, being, in one form or another, 
 promises to pay a sum of money to the bearer, but business requires 
 that thej shall pass freely from hand to hand, and that the actual 
 holder of them shall be able to exact payment independent of the 
 title of his author. (See B.-L. et Tissier. Prescription, 3rd ed. 
 n. 841; Paris, 26 nov. 1886, D. 87. 2. 110: D. X. C. C. art. 2279, 
 n. 258.) 
 
 The application of the rule in favour of the lawful possessor 
 of a corporeal moveable, including the special class of incorporeal 
 moveables just referred to, is to give to the purchaser who has got 
 delivery of the thing an enormous advantage over the purchaser 
 who has not been put in possession. To return to the previous 
 example, if I sell my horse to A, and subsequently sell it to B, 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 4-3 
 
 who is unaware of the previous sale, and B obtains delivery of it, 
 
 B, and not A, will be the owner of the horse. (C. ('. E. 46 688; 
 
 C. C. F. 1141; C. C. Q. 1027; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 2, p. 79; 
 Halton, 1, p. 140.) 
 
 We have, here, an important exception to the general rule that 
 a man cannot transfer to another any right that he lias not him- 
 self. By my sale of the horse to A, I have devested myself of 
 the property in it, and yet I am able by a subsequent sale to >B 
 to make him the owner. So much does the law favour the honest 
 buyer who obtains delivery, that even if the horse has been stolen 
 or lost, and it is afterwards bought from a horse-dealer or in a 
 public market, the buyer who is called upon to give it up to its 
 real owner is not obliged to do so except upon receiving from 
 him the price which he paid for it. (C. C. F. 2280; C. C. Q. 
 2268; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 906. 
 
 This, at any rate, is clear in the French law and in the law 
 of Quebec. The Egyptian codes say, "he can recover the price 
 paid," but they do not say that he has a right of retention till 
 he has received it. (C. C. E. 87/116; see Halton, 1. p. 220. 
 
 Does the same principle apply to the creditor who has in good 
 faith received an article in pledge and lent money upon it? The 
 prevailing view is that he is to be treated as a possessor in good 
 faith, except in a question with the owner of a thing which has 
 been stolen or lost. Although the thing did not belong to the 
 debtor, the creditor who has got possession is protected up to the 
 amount of the debt. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 415; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 2, p. 159; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 908, bis; 
 Req. 12 mars 1888, D. 88. 1. 253; C. A. Alex. 17 avr. 1900, 
 B. L. J. XII; 213; D. N. C. C. art. 2279, n. 154.) But accord- 
 ing to the jurisprudence of the Cour de Cassation, the creander- 
 gagiste does not enjoy the advantage given expressly to a buyer 
 by article 2280. The article creating an exception must be restric- 
 tively interpreted. ■ If the thing has been lost or stolen- the 
 creancier-gagiste has no protection. (Cass. 11 mai 1898, S. 98. 
 1. 481; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 2, p. 159, note 36.) This con- 
 clusion is doubted by some authorities. (Note by M. Tissier to 
 S. 98. 1. 481; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 908, bis.) 
 
46 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Incorporeal moveables. 
 
 The rule that the property of moveables is transferred by eon- 
 tract even against third parties does not apply to incorporeal 
 moveables except negotiable documents. The sale of a debt as 
 against third parties requires certain formalities which cannot 
 here be explained. (See B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 840; 
 C. C. F. 1690; C. C. Q. 1571; Halton, 2, p. 87; Beudant, 
 
 Contrats, p. 202.) 
 
 The effect of non-translatory contracts with regard to 
 third parties. 
 
 We have now discussed the ways in which those contracts which 
 are at the same time conveyances may benefit or prejudice persons 
 who were not parties to such contracts. We have now to consider 
 the contracts which do not effect any instantaneous change of 
 property, but merely generate obligations^ In such contracts a 
 third party may be introduced either in the character of a debtor 
 or in that of a creditor. Or, at any rate, if these terms are open 
 to criticism, we may say that the intention is that the third party 
 shall, in the one case, subsequently take over a liability under the 
 contract, and in the other case, that the third party shall have the 
 right to take a benefit under it. For, strictly speaking, the parties 
 to a contract cannot make a third party either a debtor or a creditor 
 under it. 
 
 The French Code states the general rule thus: — 
 
 On ne peut, en general, s engager ni stipuler en son propre 
 nom, que pour soi-meme. (C. C. F. 1119.) And it then pro- 
 ceeds in the two following articles to state as exceptions to this 
 general rule: (1) that a person may make a contract in his own 
 name for a third party if he does so in the character of a porte- 
 fort, a term to be presently explained; and, (2) that a man may 
 stipulate for the benefit of a third party subject to certain condi- 
 tions. (C. C. F. 1120-1121.) 
 
 The contract of porte-fort, as will be explained later, is in- 
 correctly treated by the code as an exception to the broad rule 
 that a man can by contract bind no one but himself. But the 
 stipulation pour autrui is in reality so important an exception to 
 the rule that a party to a contract can stipulate only for himself, 
 as completely to overshadow the rule itself. We cannot make the 
 
 
 
EFFECTS OF CONTRACTS. 47 
 
 third party a creditor, but we can stipulate a benefit for him. 
 This is a different thing from making him a creditor, but, never- 
 theless, it makes the rule of little importance. In saying that a 
 person can bind himself only the code means himself and his 
 ayants cause. And the Code of Quebec states the rule with 
 accuracy in this respect, and avoids the error into which the French 
 Code falls of treating the contract of porte-fort as an exception to 
 it, by saying, A person cannot, by a contract m Ms oivn name,, 
 bind any one but himself and his heirs and legal representatives ; 
 but he may contract in his own name that another shall perform 
 an obligation, and in this case he is liable in damages if such 
 obligation be not performed by the person indicated. (C. C. Q. 
 1028.) 
 
48 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 CONTRACT OF PORTE- FORT. 
 
 The Egyptian codes are entirely silent as to the contract of poi'te- 
 fort, though it is perfectly well recognised by the jurisprudence. 
 (C. A. Alex. 7 juin 1900, B. L. J. XII, 313; C. A. Alex. 13 
 mai 1908, B. L. J. XX, 214.) On pent se porter fort pour un 
 tiers, <>n promettant le fait de celui-ci. 
 
 Such a contract is in fact useful and valid, and there is no abso- 
 lute necessity for an article in the code to authorise it in express 
 terms, though it would have been better if the Egyptian Code 
 had contained such an article. The rule that a person cannot by a 
 contract in his own name bind any one but himself must now be 
 explained. 
 
 In saving " iji hisjrwn name " the French Code intends to 
 exclude the case where the party to the contract acts in the name 
 of another and as representing him, for example, as his agent or 
 his tutor. 
 
 The rule has no application to such a case in which the third 
 party is bound because he was represented. (Planiol, 2, n. 1019. 
 Supra, p. 13.) 
 
 Nor does it apply either to the analogous case of gestion 
 d'affaires, where the law regards the negotiorum gestor as, in a 
 sense, the agent for the person for whom he acts, although this 
 person gave him no authority. 
 
 / Here also the negotiorum gestor does not act in his own name in 
 the sense of intending to bind himself personally. 
 
 He contracts in the name and on account of the maitre. (See 
 infra, p. 155.) 
 
 This is so even where he may have been compelled to incur a 
 provisional liability. If you are in Europe, and have left your • 
 house in Egypt empty, and with no one in charge of your affairs, 
 and a wall shows signs of giving way, I, your neighbour, may 
 call in a builder to prevent the collapse. 
 
 If he agrees to do the necessary work, relying upon your paying 
 him for it, he has an action against you and no action against me. 
 
CONTRACT OF PORTE-FORT. 49 
 
 (See D. Rep. Obligations, a. 5462; note by M. Plaaiol to I). 91 . 
 1. 49; and infra, p. 155.) 
 
 But the builder may refuse to do his work unless I make myself 
 responsible. In this case, according to what seems to be the better 
 opinion, the builder will not have a direct action against you, for 
 it was with me that he contracted, and on my credit that he relied. 
 
 But I have bound you by my contract with the builder to 
 indemnify me if my. interferenjoe was justifiable, for the contract 
 which I made with the builder was on your behalf, though literally 
 it may have been made in my name. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 129, 
 and 3, nos. 2814 seq.) 
 
 The rule stated in C. O. F. 1119, does not refer at all to the 
 case of agency or to negotiorum gestio. 
 
 What is contemplated is a case where A, not being the agent of 
 B, and not acting as a negotiorwm gestor on B's behalf, neverthe- 
 less promises that B shall perform an obligation . 
 
 This promise is declared to be ineffectual. It cannot bind A, 
 for A, ex hypothesi, did not promise anything on his own account. 
 
 And it cannot bind B, for the simple reason that he never con- 
 sented to be bound. 
 
 But nothing prevents A, if he chooses, from binding himself to 
 pay damages if B does not assume liability for the contract, or, 
 in other words, if B does not ratify the engagement which A has 
 made for him. 
 
 Or, A may go further, and undertake to pay damages if B does 
 not, firstly, assume liability, and, secondly, does not duly execute 
 the contract. 
 
 The obligation of the porte-fort in the strict sense is limited to 
 this, that he undertakes to procure the ratification of a contract 
 that he makes on behalf of another. 
 
 If this is the nature of the contract, — and the words se porter 
 fort are not sacramental, — the liability of the promisor is at an 
 end when the third party has ratified. What the porte-fort pro- 
 mised was a rapporter la signature of the third party, without in 
 any way guaranteeing that, when the third party had ratified, he 
 would faithfully fulfil, the contract. 
 
 If the porte-fort promises this in addition, he is a surety — 
 caution — as well as a porte-fort. (Demolombe. 24. n. 222: B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 132.) 
 
 ■ Whether the obligation is of this wider nature, or whether it is 
 limited to that of the porte-fort in the strict sense, is purely a 
 
 w. — VOL. II. 4 
 
50 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 matter of interpretation. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 512; 
 
 Laurent, L5, n. 544; I). N. C. C. art. 1120, n. 19.) 
 
 Distinction between contract of porte-fort and suretyship. 
 
 The contract of the porte-fort must then be carefully distin- 
 guished from that of a surety. The obligation of the latter is an 
 accessory obligation to guarantee the fulfilment of a principal 
 obligation. But the obligation of the porte-fort is a principal 
 obligation, viz., to obtain the ratification of another or to pay 
 damages, and it is fulfilled if the ratification is obtained, although 
 the third party may afterwards fail to fulfil the contract. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, tU sup.; C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1900, B. L. J. XIII, 
 41; C. A. Alex. 9 mai 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 292.) 
 
 Porte-fort promises on his own account. 
 
 From what has been said already it is clear that the porte-fort 
 binds himself and not another. He binds himself to perform an 
 act, viz., to procure the ratification; not to do his best to procure 
 it, but to procure it. It is not enough for him to prove want of 
 negligence as an excuse for non-fulfilment. He can be excused 
 only by proof of force majeure which prevented him from obtain- 
 ing the ratification. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 132; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 514, note 14, ter.) 
 
 In short, the obligation of the porte-fort is simply an illustration 
 of a contract to do. And it is therefore incorrect to treat it, as 
 the French Code does, as being a promise which binds or intends 
 to bind anybody but the promisor. 
 
 If the contract is ambiguous is there a presumption that a 
 party binds himself as a porte-fort? 
 
 If the contract is ambiguous, in this sense, that it might mean 
 either, on the one hand, that the promisor promised that a third 
 party would do something, or, on the other hand, that he promised 
 to secure the ratification of the third party, is there any presump- 
 tion in favour of the latter interpretation? 
 
 This is a point upon which there has been much controversy. 
 
 According to some writers, we should apply here the rule of 
 interpretation that when a clause is susceptible of two meanings 
 it must be understood in that sense which would make it produce 
 some effect, rather than in that sense which would make it produce 
 no effect at all. (C. C. F. 1157. Supra, I, p. 372.) 
 
CONTRACT OF PORTE-FORT. 51 
 
 Now the mere promise by A thai. B will do something, if A has 
 no authority to represent B, is entirely worthless, and it is argued', 
 therefore, that the presumption is against the parties having agreed 
 to a contract which was perfectly futile. 
 
 On the other hand, if we are to presume that in every case where 
 A appears to promise that B will do something A must have 
 meant that he would secure B's ratification or pay damages, what 
 becomes of C. C. F. 1119£ 
 
 We deny practically all effect to the statement that a person 
 cannot by a contract in his own name bind any one but himself, 
 by saying that in every case where he appears to be seeking to bind 
 another he is really binding himself. The sound view appears 
 to be that a man will not be bound as a porte-fort unless the inten- 
 tion to bind himself in this way sufficiently appears, though such 
 an intention .may be inferred from the circumstances, or from 
 the whole effect of the contract without being expressed in technical 
 language as an obligation se porter fort. (Laurent, 15, n. 533; 
 Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 511; D. N. C. C. art. 1120, n. 6; 
 C. A. Alex. 23 mars 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 173.) For example, 
 if in the sale of a house the seller promises that a neighbour shall 
 cut down certain trees which block the view, it is a fair presump- 
 tion that this means that he undertakes to procure this neighbour's 
 consent . 
 
 The buyer was not likely to have contented himself with a 
 promise of no value at all. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, 
 p. 565.) 
 
 The ratification and its effect. 
 
 The ratification of the third party does not need to be in any 
 special form and it may be implied. As between the parties, the 
 ratification retroacts to the date of the contract, but as reg v ards 
 third parties the ratification takes effect only from its date, and 
 then only if it has a dale <-crhilne, or, if it is a contract subject to 
 registration, only when this formality has been complied with. 
 
 (Larombiere, art. 1120, n. 7; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 142 (1). 
 See, however, Cass. 18 dec. 1875, D. 76. 1. 97. and the note.) 
 
 Utility of contract of porte-fort. 
 
 It is principally where incapable persons, and especially minors, 
 are concerned, that the contract of porte-fort is very convenient. 
 For example, co-heirs desire to sell the property which they hold 
 in undivided ownership, and among them there are minors. In 
 
 4 (2) 
 
52 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 order to- avoid the expense and delay of legal proceedings, the- 
 co-heirs who have attained majority sell on their own behalf, and 
 at the same time se portent fort for the minors, that is guarantee 
 that these will ratify the sale when they come of age, or that, if 
 they refuse to do so, the co-heirs will pay the damages. This is 
 the common case, but a person may, if he chooses, undertake to 
 secure the ratification by any third party, whether capable or 
 incapable, of a contract made on behalf of this person. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 134; Planiol, 2, n. 1022.) 
 
 There is a certain analogy between the position of a porte-fort 
 and that of a person who professes to act as an agent, though he 
 has no authority, or of one who, being an agent, exceeds his 
 authority, without having given to the other party a sufficient 
 knowledge of the limits of his authority. The agent in such a 
 case binds himself. (C. C. E. 524/643; C. C. F. 1997; Douai, 
 25 janv. 1897, D. 97. 2. 319; C. A. Alex. 16 nov. 1905, B. L. J. 
 XVIII, 15.) 
 
 It may happen that a person contracts both for himself and 
 also as porte-fort for another. In that case, he has a direct and 
 personal right to sue for execution of the contract, and it is no 
 answer to plead that the third party for whom he contracted had 
 no legal existence, being, for example, an unincorporated society. 
 (Cass. 27 juillet 1903, D. 1904. 1. 36.) And a contract may 
 be made by which A promises that B will do something, or, if B 
 fails to do it, that he will do it himself. (Beaubien v. Ekers, 
 1902, K. J. Q. 24 S. C. 199.) 
 
 Such a contract must not be confused with the contract of 
 porte-fort . 
 
 English law as to person who professes to be an agent though 
 he has no authority. 
 
 The principle of the English laAv is that if the alleged agent 
 honestly believed that he had authority he is liable on an implied 
 warranty of his authority. (Storkey v. Bank of England, 1903, 
 A. C. 114, 72 L.J. Ch.402.) 
 
 If he knew he had no authority he is liable for deceit. (Polhill 
 v. Walter, 1832, 3 B. & Ad. 114, 37 R. R. 344; Anson, Contracts,^ 
 14th ed. 415; Pollock, Contracts, 8th ed. p. 113.) 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 53 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES, 
 OR THE STIPULATION POUR AUTRUI. 
 
 We now pass from promises made on behalf of a third party to 
 the converse case of stipulations made for the benefit of a third 
 party. ' We have seen that, without consent, the third party cannot 
 be made a, debtor. In like manner, he cannot be made a creditor, 
 or, at any rate, he cannot be compelled to take a benefit under the 
 •contract, though he may be given an opportunity of doing so. 
 The article in the French Code reads: A party may, in like 
 manner, stipulate for the benefit of a third party, when such a 
 stipulation is the condition of a contract which he makes far 
 himself, or of a gift which he makes to another, and he who makes 
 the stipulation cannot revoke it if the third party have signified 
 his unsh to take the benefit thereof. (C. C. F. 1121.) 
 
 The Civil Code of Quebec is to the same effect. (C. C. Q. 
 1029.) 
 
 The article on this subject in the Egyptian codes is more meagre, 
 but it, no doubt, intends to lay down the same principle: When 
 a person has stipulated on behalf of a third party ivithout his 
 mandate, such third party hm the option of ratifying the con- 
 tract or of refusing to recognise it. (C. C. E. 137/198.) 
 
 History of the stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 The article of the French Code states in brief form the law of 
 the subject as given by Pothier. (Oblig. nos. 70—72.) But, 
 to understand it, it is necessary to go back to the Roman law, and 
 to the old French law which was based upon it. The general rule 
 of the Roman law is expressed very roundly thus: Alteri stipidari 
 nemo potest. (Inst. 3. 19. 19.) 
 
 The reason given for this is that the stipulator has no interest. 
 If I stipulate that you shall pay a certain sum to Paul, I cannot 
 enforce the contract unless I can show an interest. If, however, 
 I have stipulated that, in the event of your failing to pay to Paul 
 
54 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the sum agreed upon, you shall pay mo a penalty, this removes the 
 difficulty, because then I have an interest. And, in this case, 
 the principal obligation is that you snail pay me a penalty in a 
 certain event. This gets over the objection sometimes urged that 
 the clause of penalty is accessory, and, therefore, if the principal 
 obligation is null the accessory obligation falls Avith it. (Pothicr, 
 Obliq. n. 70. But, even in the Roman law, there were several 
 j> oases in which a stipulation in favour of a third party was held 
 to he effectual, though the stipulator had no pecuniary interest, and 
 though no penalty had been stipulated. The principal one was 
 where a donor in making a donation stipulated that it was subject 
 to the charge that the donee should pay something to a third 
 party. This was called a donatio sub modo. (Code, 8. 55. 1; 
 Dig ^24. 3. 45. SeeGirard, Manuel, 5th eel. p. 946; and, for 
 other less important cases, Windscheid, Pandekten, 2, s. 316.) 
 
 The glossators, or mediaeval commentators on the Roman law, 
 extended this principle to all cases where something had been 
 delivered to a party, where there had been a dation, whether upon 
 the title of donation or upon any other title such as sale. This 
 was accepted law in Pothier's time, and some of the old French 
 writers before then had gone a step further, in saying that, when- 
 ever in a contract A promised something to B, or delivered some- 
 thing to B on condition that B should confer a benefit on C, the 
 stipulation for C's benefit was valid. (See, for the history, Lam- 
 bert. E., Du Contrat en faveur de Tiers, n. 8 and n. 56; Planiol, 
 2, nos 1212 seq.) 
 
 The code adopted this view, for the general principle of the 
 modern law is that mere consent is enough to bind, and it is 
 inconsistent with this principle that any dation or delivery should 
 be required to make the contract complete. 
 
 Prom this review, it will be seen that the rule that one can 
 stipulate only for oneself becomes of very limited application. If 
 I stipulate merely that you shall give something to A, this is not 
 binding unless I have a pecuniary interest, in which case, in spite 
 of appearances, I am really stipulating for myself as well as for 
 A. But if, in a contract agreed to by you, I promise you any- 
 thing, or give you anything, and I stipulate as a condition that you 
 shall give something to A, this is a valid contract which I, the 
 stipulator, can enforce. And, in this latter case, it is not necessary 
 for me to have a pecuniary interest; it is enough if I have a 
 moral interest, such as the mere desire to confer a favour upon the 
 third party. 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 55 
 
 l'-.-L. el Barde, 1, n. 149; Cass. 30 avril 1888, D. 88. 1. 
 291.) 
 
 IF a pecuniary interest were require d, the utility of the stipu- 
 lation pour autrui would be greatly dimi nisli«il . If I insure my 
 life for the benefit of a third party I have no pecuniary interest; 
 for nothing- will be paid to me, and the money when it is paid will 
 nol form part of my succession, but my moral interest is sufficient 
 to make the contract valid. (Cass. 6 fevrier 1888, D. 88. 1. 
 193; Cass. 16 .Janvier 1888, D. 88. 1. 77.) 
 
 Modern applications of the stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 In the Roman law, and in the old French law, the stipulation 
 p&ur autrui played a comparatively small part. But in the 
 modern law it forms one of the most important chapters. No 
 principle of the Law has been found to be more flexible, or more 
 capabh of being- applied to new sets of circumstances. It has 
 been employed, as Planiol says, a realiser des operations qui 
 seraienl Impossibles on, tout au moins, plus difficiles avec tous les 
 autres principes du droit. (2, n. 1216.) 
 
 The whole law of life-insurance, when the capital is to be paid 
 to third parties, and -the law of accident-insurance by an employer 
 for the benefit of his workmen, are two only of the many applica- 
 tions of this principle, and new cases to which it can be applied 
 are continually occurring. (See Lambert, Control en faveur de 
 Ti<rs } n. 198; Planiol, 1. c.) If a lessee assigns his lease, as 
 he may do unless there is a stipulation to the contrary, the assign- 
 ment is another example of the stipulation pour autrui. The 
 assignment of a lease is a different contract from the granting of a 
 sub-lease. (See C. C. E: 366/449; C. C. F. 1717; C. C. Q. 
 1638. A The sub-lease is a new contract of lease intended to pro- 
 duce effects only between the original lessee and the sub-tenant, 
 and not to give the original lessor any direct action against the 
 sub-tenant. (See C. A. Alex. 21 mars 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 
 222.) 
 
 The assignment of a lease, on the other hand, is the sale of an 
 incorporeal right — transport de oreance — the object of which is 
 to transfer to the assignee or cessiownmre all the rights which the 
 assignor had under the lease. 
 
 It does not relieve the original lessee of his obligations to his 
 lessor, unless the lessor chooses to release him. but it gives to the 
 original lessor a second debtor, independent of any acceptance. 
 
56 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 He can, it' he chooses, bring a direct action against the assignee 
 to make him fulfil all the obligations of the lease. (B.-L. et 
 Wahl, Louage, 1, u. 1140; D. N. C. C. art. 1717, n. 80; Lam- 
 bert, op. cit. n. 233; Halton, 2, p. 136. Cf. in Quebec, Authier 
 v. Driscoll, 1912, K. J. Q. 42 S. C. 52; Mignault, Droit Civil 
 Cemadien, 7, p. 318.) 
 
 The assignor has, therefore, made a valid stipulation for the 
 benefit of his landlord. 
 
 - In France, the principle of the stipulation pour autrui has been 
 applied in the ease of charitable foundations, made in the form of a 
 charge or condition attached to a legacy . If, for example, a legacy, 
 is left to the maire of a conVmune for the benefit of the poor of that 
 commune, the testator stipulates for the benefit of people unknown 
 to him and for generations unborn. (See Bordeaux, 27 fevr. 
 1905, D. 1905. 2. 327.) 
 
 It has been made possible in this way to give a right to persons 
 independent of their acceptance, and to future persons as well as to 
 persons already existing. If we treated such charitable bequests 
 as cases either of donation or of legacy, both of these results appear 
 to be excluded by the article of the French Code which says that, 
 in order to be capable to receive emtre-i'ifs, a donee must have been 
 'conceived at the moment of the donation, and, in order to be 
 capable of receiving under a will, the beneficiary must have been 
 conceived at the date of the testator's death. 
 
 ('. G. F. 906; C. G Q. 765, 838; Lambert, Du Contrat en 
 javeur de Tiers, n. 328; D. N. C. C. art. 906, n. 64;. Caen, 
 15 nov. 1906, D. 1907. 2. 265, and dissertation by M. Planiol; 
 and, for the interesting analogy between such cases and what are 
 called in English law '■trusts,'' see the dissertation by M. Levy- 
 Ullmann in note to Cass. 12 mai 1902, S. 1905. 1. 137; am«d 
 Paris, 18 fevr. 1909, D. 1909. 2. 273; and the dissertation by 
 M. Planiol in note to Cass. 14 fevr. 1906, 1). 1907. 1. 313.) 
 
 In Egypt the capacity to receive depends on the personal law, 
 and the institution of the Wakf to a great extent prevents those 
 difficulties arising which have led to so much discussion in France. 
 „ Other interesting and important applications of the stipulation 
 pour autrui are found: (1) in contracts made by a department 
 of the government, or by some public body in which stipulations 
 are contained for the benefit of third parties. 
 
 When, for example, a municipality invites tenders for the con- 
 struction of public works, it frequently inserts conditions for the 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 57 
 
 benefit of the workmen to be employed. Such clauses are called 
 cahiers des charges d 1 adjudication. It may say, for instance, that 
 although the contractor shall be entitled to sub-let part of the 
 contract, he shall remain liable to compensate all the workmen 
 employed who are the victims of an industrial accident. (Paris, 
 6 fevr. 1908, D. 1908.2. 185.) 
 
 Or, it may be made a condition that the workmen shall be paid 
 a minimum wage, or that the working hours shall not exceed a 
 certain number per day. 
 
 (2) In contracts of public utility, that is, in contracts made 
 between the government or a public body for the performance of 
 some public service, such as the supply of water, gas, electric light 
 and power, and the like, there are frequently stipulations for the 
 benefit of the public within the municipality or other area in 
 question. And if the intention appears to be to confer upon 
 members of the public a direct right, any one of these members of 
 the public within the area can sue for the execution of the contract, 
 or for damages caused by its breach. (C. Cass. Beige, 21 juill. 
 1888, S. 89. 4. 9, and note by M. Labbe; Lambert, Contrat en 
 faveur de Tiers, n. 319; Planiol, 2, n. 1216. Cf. in Quebec, 
 Markham v. Montreal Gas Co., 1908, R. J. Q. 34 S. C. 10.) 
 
 And so, in an Egyptian case, where the government made a 
 contract with a water company at Alexandria to supply water to 
 the city on certain terms, it was held that this gave any citizen of 
 Alexandria a direct action against the water company. (0. A. 
 Alex. 20 dec. 1894, B. L. J. VII, 46. Cf. 0. A. Alex. 3 juin 
 1896, B. L. J. VIII, 313.) 
 
 But the government, or any other public authority, may, and 
 often does, make contracts in the public interest which are, never- 
 theless, not intended to give any rights of action to members of 
 the public. 
 
 It is a question of interpretation. (See C. A. Alex. 17 mai 
 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 283.) Perhaps, as M. Planiol contends, 
 the public authority, when it contracts for the benefit, of members 
 of the public, does so as their mandatory. The public is not autrui 
 for the authority which it has put in power to act on its behalf. 
 (Planiol, 2, n. 1216, note 4.) 
 

 58 TH"E LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Public subscriptions. 
 
 Difficult ;iiul delicate questions arise in regard to the law of 
 public subscriptions. 1 1 a newspaper publishes that it will receive 
 subscriptions for the benefit of those who have suffered from an 
 earthquake, or if a committee is organised to receive subscriptions 
 for a monument to Lord Kitchener, what are the legal relations 
 which exist between (a) the subscriber and the organiser; (b) the 
 Subscriber and the beneficiary; and (c) the organiser and the 
 beneficiary? 
 
 The French authors' throw little light upon these problems, 
 but so far as there can be said to be any accepted view, it would 
 seem to be that organisers of public subscriptions are to be regarded 
 as the mandataries of the subscribers. (Hue, 8, n. 376; Paris, 
 21 oct. 1902, D. 1903. 2. 121; Cass. 6 fevr. 1888, D. 88. 1. 
 79, and the note; Bourges, ler mai 1900, D. 1900. 2. 425, and 
 the note; Cass. 3 mars 1885, S. 85. 1. 168, IX 85. 1. 411. See 
 D. N. C. C, Addition*, 1913, arts. 1105 and 1106, nos. 29—2 
 seq.) 
 
 The difficulty of the case arises from the fact that there are 
 three parties whose interests have to be considered. If we are 
 to look upon it as a mandate given by the subscribers to the com- 
 mittee or to the organisers of the fund, it is not possible to give 
 a. direct right of action to the beneficiaries ./'And, in other ways, 
 the relation if it is mandate is mandate of a very special kind. 
 . ,ln mandate the mandator can at any time revoke, and the manda- 
 tary can claim his expenses from the mandator, and it is the 
 mandator's business which the mandata/y is charged to do. 
 
 Are any of these things true here?/ A more satisfactory way 
 of regarding the transaction is to say, with M. Claro, that a 
 public subscription is at the same time a gift and a commutative 
 contract. The relation of the subscriber to the beneficiary is that 
 of donor and donee. But there is, at the same time, a oommutative 
 contract between the subscriber and the organiser of the sub- 
 scription. 
 
 The subscriber stipulates with the organiser of the subscription 
 for the benefit of the beneficiary. 
 
 The manner in which the subscriptions have been collected and 
 the other circumstances vary greatly in different cases, and the 
 legal situation is not always the same. 
 
 In the ordinary case, at any rate, it would seem that the sub- 
 scribers will have a right to claim the return of their subscription 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 59 
 
 if from a cause independent of their will, it becomes impossible 
 to carry out the end which they had in view. 
 
 And if the subscription was begun without the knowledge of 
 the beneficiary, he has a right to put a stop to it if he likes, and 
 he has an interest in insisting on the subscribers being informed 
 that he is opposed to taking the benefit proposed. (Paris, 21 oet. 
 1902, D. 1903. 2. 121.) 
 
 It would be intolerable if people could put up a statue of a, 
 man against his will. (See the notes of M. Claro to Paris, 22 oet. 
 1902, and Bourges, ler mai 1900, ut sup. Cf. Queinnec, A., Be 
 la Nature des Souscriptions organisees, Caen, 1904, These.) 
 
 These are by no means the only illustrations which might be 
 given of the application of the principle of stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 It is mainly by the application of this principle that the French 
 jurisprudence has contrived to find a way out of some difficulties 
 which in the English law are solved more satisfactorily by the 
 equitable doctrine of the trust. 
 
 Many other cases. 
 
 There are many other eases in which it may be found that there 
 was a stipulation for the benefit of another. 
 
 In a recent French case an employer of labour made a contract 
 with a doctor for medical attendance upon his employees, and a 
 deduction was made from their wag'es in consequence. 
 • The question was whether this gave one of them a direct right 
 of action against the doctor under the contract. 
 
 The court held that an employee had a direct action against 
 the doctor for neglecting or refusing without justification to attend 
 him. (Pau, 30 juin 1913, D. 1915. 2. 49. ) 
 
 Stipulation pour autrui is not presumed. 
 
 Exceptions to the rules of law are not to be admitted unless 
 there is a clear indication that they were intended by the parties. 
 
 And the stipulation pour autrui is such an exception. Thus 
 in an Egyptian case it was said: La disposition de V article 198 
 du Code Civil Mixte etablit une exception au principe general 
 quon ne peut s 'engager ni stipuler en son prop-e nom que pour 
 soi-meme ; mais elle doit etr.e restrictivement interpretee et pour 
 receuoir son application suppose necessairement et comme condition 
 sine qua nou qn'il u a une stipulation expresse on formelle au 
 profit d'un tiers. (Alex. 22 janv. 1910; Savour, Rep. n. 792.) 
 
«0 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Right of the third party for whom a benefit is stipulated. 
 
 Does the third party acquire a right of action, and if so, of 
 what nature is his right, and upon what principle can it be 
 explained? 
 
 To these questions the codes return a very inadequate answer. 
 
 The French Code says he who makes the stipulation cannot 
 revoke it if the third party has signified his assent to it. 
 
 The Egyptian Code does not even say so much as this, but 
 merely that the third party has the choice of confirming the con- 
 tract or of refusing to recognise it. 
 
 It is clear, at any rate, that the third party cannot be compelled 
 to take a benefit. 
 
 But, subject to this qualification, is it possible to give to the 
 third party a direct right of action, and, if so, upon what theory 
 may this be defended? 
 
 Further, is it the intention of the law that the third party, 
 should have an immediate right from the date of the contract, 
 although such a right is declared b}^ the French Code to be re- 
 vocable by the stipulator at any time before the third party has 
 signified his assent to it, or is there no right acquired 'until the 
 assent is signified, just as in an ordinary contract the offeree has 
 no right before acceptance? 
 
 These questions have led to great discussion, and, although an 
 agreement has been reached with regard to some of the results, 
 there are still many differences of opinion as to the principle upon 
 which these results rest. 
 
 It is now generally agreed both in the doctrine and the jurispru- 
 dence that an inchoate right in the third party is created by the 
 contract itself. His assent is not needed to create the right; the 
 right is already created for him to take it or leave it, although at 
 present it is revocable. 
 
 (Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 47; Colin et Capitant,, 
 2, p. 340; Beq. 20 dec. 1898, D. 99. 1. 320; B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 154; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, n. 50; Capitant, in Livre du 
 Centenaire, 1, 535. Contra, Laurent, 15, n. 559.) 
 
 The question is of great practical importance. If no right vests 
 in the third party till his assent is signified, and if he dies before 
 giving such assent, the right will never come into existence, for 
 it is only vested rights which are transmissible to heirs. But 
 the view which tends to prevail in France is that the right of the 
 third party is acquired by the contract, and, consequently, is trans- 
 

 STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 61 
 
 « 
 mil ted to his heirs who can assent to it unless it has been revoked. 
 (B.-L. el Barde, 1, n. 154(1); Aubrv el Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 523; 
 Cass. 8 fevr. 1888, D. 88. 1. 193; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, n.53. 
 Cf. same rule in Quebec, Robitaille v. Trudel, 1899, R. J. Q. 
 16 S. C. 39. ^Moreover, it is generally agreed that if the stipu- 
 lator dies before the third party has signified his assent, this 
 does not deprive the third party of his right to signify his assent 
 afterwards. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 154 (1); D. N. C. C. art. 1121, 
 n. 74; Cass. 22 juin 1891, D. 92. 1. 205; C. A. Alex. 18 janv. 
 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 163.) And, lastly, it is generally agreed 
 that, unless a contrary intention appears, the heirs of the stipu- 
 lator succeed him in the right to revoke the benefit at any time 
 before the third party has assented to it. (Planiol, 2, n. 1250;. 
 B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 171; Bordeaux, ler avr. 1897, D. 98. 2. 
 169; D. N. 0. C. art. 1121, n. 80.) 
 
 The rights on both sides are looked upon as rights transmissible 
 to heirs according to the general rule, though, as we shall see,, 
 this is subject to an important exception. 
 
 Assuming that these points are settled in practice, it remains 
 to consider upon what principle they are to be explained. This 
 may, perhaps, appear to be an illogical method. 
 
 It may be said that we ought to "begin by stating what we 
 conceive to be the sound theory, and then give the practical illus- 
 trations of it* But in this case, there is a convenience in following 
 the reverse method, because the theory itself has been shaped and 
 rendered precise in order to meet certain practical needs, parti- 
 cularly in regard to life insurance. 
 
 To make the contract of life insurance useful, it is absolutely 
 necessary that the beneficiary shouldd have an independent right 
 — a droit propre — that he shall be able to accept this right after 
 the death of the assured, and that, if he accepts it, the money shall 
 be"regarded as coming to him directly from the insurance company, 
 and not from the succession of the deceased. 
 
 If the money were to be considered as coming out of the succes- 
 sion, and the deceased died insolvent, his creditors would be able 
 to claim it, and this is one of the possibilities which the assured 
 desires to exclude. In addition to this point, there are other 
 considerations important for a person who insures his life, such as 
 the possibility of insuring for the benefit of unborn children, 
 which may yet lead to further modifications of the theory. (See 
 Lambert, Du Contrat en favew die Tiers, n. 251; Dupuich, P., 
 Assurance sur la Vie, n. 74; Lefort, J., Assurance sur la Vie, 2,. 
 
62 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 p. 258; C. A. Alex. 11 few. 1900, B. L. J. XII, 111; C. A. 
 Alex. 28 now 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 27. Cf. C. A. Alex. 30 mai 
 1894, B. L. J. VI, 308; C. A. Alex. 25 avril 1895, B. L..J. 
 VII, 263.) 
 
 Upon what principle, then, may we justify the result at which 
 the courts have arrived? There are four theories on the subject. 
 Let us take for the sake of clearness the example common in 
 practice of a donation subject to a charge in favour of a third 
 party. This is, in fact, the classical example of the Roman law. 
 For instance, I give you my farm subject to the charge that you 
 pay an annual allowance to my son. What is the nature of" such 
 a contract? 
 
 (1) Theory of the offer. 
 
 The first theory, which is called the theory of the offer, is that 
 such a contract as I have mentioned may be analysed into two 
 parts . 
 
 There is (1) a contract completed between you and me, and 
 there is also (2) an offer by me to my son of the sum stipulated 
 for, and this offer becomes a contract if my son accepts it. (Colmet 
 de Santerre, 5, n. 33, bis, IV. See Saleilles, Theorie Generate de 
 VObligaiirm, 3rd ed. n. 248.) 
 
 But this explanation of the contract seems to be contrary to the 
 true intention of the parties. In any ordinary contract it is the 
 person who makes the offer who is bound to execute the contract 
 if his offer is accepted. 
 
 But here, according to this theory, I make the offer, and. yet, 
 if my son accepts it, it is you who must execute the contract. 
 Accordingly, another variant of this theory is that the matter may 
 be analysed thus: I make an offer to you and you accept it, and 
 it is a term of your acceptance that you in turn should make an 
 implied offer to my son. 
 
 (Larombiere on art. 1121, n. 7; Thaller, in note to Besaneon, 
 2 mars 1887, D. 88. 2. 1.) 
 
 This is even more artificial. Is it likely that I intend my sons 
 right to be dependent on your choosing to make the offer? And, 
 ^U even if we admit that you are bound to make the offer, still no 
 right could possibly vest in my son until the offer is made. Until 
 that time, the right must be vested in me. Now, this is precisely 
 what I desire to avoid. I want a right to vest in my son at once. 
 (See Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 341; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, 
 n. 216.; 
 
 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 63 
 
 Moreover, my intention in the ordinary ease is not to give m\ 
 son the right to bring an action against me, but only against yon. 
 How can this be contingent on your choosing to make him an 
 offer? (See B.-L. et Barde, Oblig.\, n. 158; Cass. (J juin 1888, 
 D. 89. 1. 55; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, n. 141.) 
 
 Take the common case of life-assurance. For instance, I insure 
 my life for my son's benefit. 
 
 It is, surely, a very false explanation to say that the insurance 
 company is to make an offer to my son. Moreover, whether we 
 regard the case as one of an offer by the stipulator or by the 
 promisor, the theory is open to a fatal objection. An offer, accord- 
 ing to the principles of contract, falls to the ground if the offeror 
 dies, or loses capacity, before it is accepted. And it falls to the 
 ground, likewise, if the offeree dies before accepting it. He had 
 no vested right, and could transmit no right to his heirs. 
 
 For, in neither of these cases, is there that meeting of the two' 
 minds— that consensus in idem — which the law requires for the 
 formation of a contract. But, we have seen, that in practice the 
 law is settled that in a stipulation for the benefit of a third party, 
 the assent of the third party may be given after the death of the 
 stipulator, and, that if the third party dies before assent, his 
 heirs, can assent in his place. So that, clearly, the jurisprudence 
 does not treat this as being a case of the acceptance of an offer. 
 If it did, life-insurance for the benefit of a third party would 
 lose much of its value. If a man insured his life for his wife's 
 benefit, it would not be until he died that she would have any right . 
 and, if the case were treated as being an offer made by the assured, 
 the offer which the husband made would fall at his death, so that 
 she could no longer accept it. 
 
 It would certainly seem a strange thing if the law were to 
 make impossible, or, at the least, were to hamper at every turn, a 
 contract so eminently desirable as a life-insurance for the benefit 
 of the family of the assured, and yet, if we adopt the theory of the 
 offer, this would be the result. 
 
 But, in fact, the theory of the offer has nothing to recommend 
 it. It was not the theory of the old French writers; it is not 
 implied in the language of the code, and it leads to practical 
 results of a most unsatisfactory kind. 
 
 As regards the language of the code, the French Code studiously 
 avoids calling the assent of the third party "acceptance. 
 
 It says celui qui a fait cette stipulation ne pent la rrroqnrr si 
 le tiers a declare vouloir .en profiter, which the Code of Quebec 
 
 ■ 
 
64 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 translates by: " If the third person have signified his assent to it." 
 (C. C. F. 1121; C. C. Q. 1029.) 
 
 This rather roundabout phrase is used apparently in preference 
 to " acceptance,' in order to indicate that it is not a mere offer 
 which is made to the third party, but that an inchoate right ha® 
 been created in his favour, if he chooses to take it. (B.-L. eti 
 Barde, 1, n. 154; C. C. F. 1121; C. C. Q. 1029.) 
 
 In the recent French jurisprudence the theory of the offer may 
 be said to have been definitely rejected. 
 
 (Saleilles, Theorie gen. de V Obligation, p. 278; Lambert, Con- 
 trat en javehtr de Tiers, n. 15; Caiss. 24 fevr. 1902, D. 1903. 1. 
 433, and note by M. Dupuich; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, 
 n. 14. 
 
 In Egypt, the Mixed Court of Appeal, in one case at leasts 
 seems to have accepted this theory. (C. A. Alex. 25 avr. 1895, 
 B. L. J. VII, 263.) 
 
 (2) Theory of implied assignment. 
 
 The second theory is that in the stipulation pour autrui there 
 is concealed an implied assignment or cession de creance. 
 
 It is said that if I insure my life for your benefit, I acquire a 
 right against the insurance-company, which I then by implication 
 assign to you . But in that case at my death, the insurance money 
 would form part of my succession, and would be available for 
 my creditors before you came in, if I were to die insolvent. 
 
 And if, as in the ordinary case, I have the right to revoke the 
 insurance in your favour during my lifetime, and I became in- 
 solvent, my creditors would be entitled to revoke in* my stead. 
 This result would destroy one of the objects of insurance, viz., 
 to provide a fund secured from the creditors of the assured. This 
 difficult}' can be got over only by ruling that the insurance-money 
 is not to be regarded as stipulated by the assured for himself, and 
 then, afterwards, ceded by him to the third party, but that, on 
 the other hand, the third party acquires an immediate right to it 
 under the contract of insurance itself. 
 
 As the French and the Egyptian courts both take this view, 
 they clearly reject the theory of implied assignment. (Cass. 1 
 27 mars 1888, S. 88. 1. 121, D. 88. 1. 193; Paris, 10 mars 
 1896, D. 96. 2. 465; Rouen, 6 avr. 1895, D. 95. 2. 545. See 
 article by M. Wahl in Rev. Trim. 1, p. 24; Lefort, Assurance 
 sur to Vie, 2, p. 225; and M. Thaller's note to Besangon, 2 mars 
 1887, D. 1888. 2. 1.) 
 
 4<L 
 
 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 65 
 
 Tho Mixed Court of Appeal has followed the French jurispru- 
 dence in admitting the droit proprs of the beneficiary, and in' 
 holding that the insurance-money never enters the patrimony of 
 the stipulator. (C. A. Alex. 18 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 
 163; C. A. Alex. 28 nov. 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 27. Cf. Wind- 
 scheid, PandeMen, 8th ed. 2, s. 316, a.) 
 
 (3) Theory of negotiorum gestio. 
 
 The third theory to explain how the third party comes into the 
 contract is the theory of gestion d'affaires. It is maintained that 
 if I make a donation to you, subject to the charge that you pay a 
 sum to my son, I am acting as a negotiorum gestor for my son,. 
 
 When he signifies his assent, he ratifies what I have done. This 
 theory has been supported by very eminent French writers, and 
 has been adopted by the courts in many cases. The case of col- 
 lective insurance of his workmen by an employer has been treated 
 as an example of gestion d'affaires. (See Lambert, Du Contrat en 
 favour de Tiers, n. 280; Montpellier, 5 mai 1888, D. 88. 2. 292; 
 Demolombe, 24, nos. 236 seq. ; Labbe, in Note to Douai, 14 
 fevr. 1887, S. 88. 2. 49; Planiol, 2, n. 1222; Douai, 24 dec. 
 1889, S. 91. 2. 113; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, nos. 28 seq.) 
 
 It does not seem to be a satisfactory explanation. It is true 
 that, as Planiol says, a man who makes a contract for the benefit 
 of another may be a negotiorum gestor. If I find your horse 
 straying twenty miles away from home, I may contract with a 
 railway company to carry it back home, and, though I make th^ 
 contract in my own name, I make it as a negotiorum gestor for 
 you. 
 
 But does such a case really resemble a donation subject to a 
 charge or an insurance for the benefit of a third party? Is it 
 analogous to the ease of my insuring my life for the benefit of 
 my son? 
 
 The principle underlying negotiorum gestio is that the law 
 does not allow unjust enrichment. If, out of kindness, I step in 
 voluntarily to do something for your benefit, and in so doing, I 
 put myself to expense, the law will not allow you to take the 
 benefit without paying me what I am out of pocket. In acting 
 as I do. I know that I shall have a claim for reimbursement, 
 and you cannot choose whether you will ratify or not, if your 
 affairs have been well managed by me; or, in other words, if a 
 benefit to vou has resulted. But if I insure my life for my son's 
 
 
 w. — VOL. II. 
 
66 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 benefit, I am not looking to him for any reimbursement, nor has 
 my act laid him under any legal liability to me. 
 
 Ho is perfectly free to take the assurance-money or to leave it, 
 but what I have secured for him is a right to claim it. It seems 
 to me t hat nothing can be more strained than to treat this as a case 
 of gestion d'affaires. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 518; Laurent, 
 15, n. 557; Pond. Frang. Oblig. n. 7450.) 
 
 (4) Theory of the droit propre. 
 
 The fourth theory is that by the contract itself a direct and 
 immediate right is given to the third party. This is called by 
 the French writers the theory of the droit propre or the droit 
 direct. (Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 14; Lambert, Contrat 
 en faveiir de Tiers, n. 122; note by M. Dupuich to Trib. Civ. 
 de Toulouse, 21 fevr. 1902, D. 1902. 2. 329; Colin et Capitant, 
 2, p. 342.) 
 
 The contract itself affects the third party, contrary to the general 
 rule that the contract can affect only the parties to it. It is an 
 exception to this rule, and is stated to be so in the French Code 
 itself. (C. C. F. 1165; C. C. Q. 1029; Bufnoir, Propriete et 
 Contrat, p. 577.) It is true that to say that we have here an 
 exception to the general rule of contract is to state the fact without 
 explaining it, but if the law recognises the possibility of a contract 
 affecting a third party, subject to certain conditions, we are bound 
 to accept this whether we can bring it under some more general 
 rule of the law or not . Pothier was content to say that, though a 
 contract could not propria virtute give a right to a third part}-, 
 yet e'est Vequite naturelle qui forme cet engagement. {Oblig. 
 n. 72.) 
 
 We may say, at any rate, by way of explanation, that we have, 
 to begin with, a valid contract between the stipulator and the» 
 promisor. Now what is the act to which the promisor binds 
 himself? It is to hold himself bound to the third party unless the 
 stipulator changes his mind. The object of the contract is this 
 obligation in favour of the third party. 
 
 This object is not impossible or illicit, and it springs out of a 
 completed contract between the stipulator and the promisor. (See 
 Saleilles, Theorie Generate ch V Obligation, 3rd ed. p. 275.) As 
 Ave have seen, the courts in France and in Egypt have now de- 
 finitely accepted the view that an immediate right, or droit propre, 
 can be given to the third party in this way provided that the 
 
 
 - "... 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 67 
 
 third party is sufficiently determined. (Cass. 28 avril 1903, D. 
 1904. 1. 150; C. A. Alex. 28 nov. 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 27; 
 C. A. Alex. 18 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 163.) 
 
 In the last case the Mixed Court of Apipeal said: Le droit du 
 tiers au benefice d'une assurance est repute prendre naissance a 
 son profit au moment meme ou le contrat se for'me entre le stipu- 
 lant et le promettant, sous la seule condition de sa ratification 
 ulterieure . 
 
 The theory of the droit propre is now very generally accepted 
 by la doctrine in France. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 161; Lambert, 
 Contrat en fawur de Tiers, n. 117; Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, 
 p. 576; Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 225, and authorities 
 there given.) 
 
 Nor is there any weight in the argument sometimes advanced 
 that it is contrary to legal principles that a man should acquire a 
 right resulting from a contract to which he was not a party and 
 made without his knowledge. It happens, commonly enough, 
 that a man acquires a right without his knowledge, and without 
 his participation, in the case of delicts and quasi-delicts. If a 
 man wrongfully injures my property, in my absence and without 
 my knowledge, I acquire a right of action against him which is 
 transmissible to my heirs. Why should there be any greater 
 difficulty when two persons without my knowledge agree to give 
 me a right of action? 
 
 One person alone could not give me such a right, because there 
 would be no contract, and, according to the principles of the French 
 law, a purely unilateral declaration of will, not being a testament, 
 cannot create either a right or a,n obligation. But, when there is 
 a contract under which two parties agree to give a right to a third 
 party, why is this not sufficient? And even the most rigorous 
 supporters of strict legal principle, if they do not admit that 
 the parties to a contract could give such a right to a third party 
 without an express provision of law, can hardly deny that the 
 law can give to them such a power. 
 
 The French Code distinctly does this when it says that agree- 
 ments produce effects only between the parties and do not benefit 
 a third party, except in the case of a stipulation pour autrui. 
 (C. C. F. 1165.) 
 
 It would be difficult to find a clearer way of saying that under 
 the stipidation pour autrui the contract itself, contrary to the 
 general rule, does affect, directly a person who was not a party to 
 it. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 583.) 
 
 «) St - 5 ^ :; " 
 
 V 
 
68 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The Egyptian Code lias no such precise statement, but it is 
 quite improbable, that any change in the law was intended. 
 
 Theory of droit propre accepted in German Code. 
 
 The matter is dealt with admirably in the German Code in a 
 series of articles. 
 
 By contract a performance in favour of a third party can be 
 stipulated for, with this effect that the third party acquires a 
 direct right to enforce the performance. 
 
 In default of a special provision as to this point, the court must 
 determine from the circumstances, and particularly from the pur- 
 pose of the contract, whether the third party acquires such a 
 right, and in this case if the right was intended, to arise imme- 
 diately or only after certain antecedent conditions have been ful- 
 filled, and also whether the parties to the contract have reserved 
 to themselves the power to revoke or modify the right of the 
 third party without his consent (art. 328). 
 
 //, by a contract, one of the parties binds himself to pay a 
 creditor of the other party, without however assuming the debt, 
 it is presumed, in case of doubt, that the creditor does not acquire 
 the right to sue this party directly for payment (art. 329). 
 
 // in a contract of life insurance, or for the constitution of a 
 life-rent, the payment of the capital insured or that of the life- 
 rent has been stipulated for the benefit of a third party, it is 
 presumed, in case of doubt, that the third party acquires directly 
 the right to sue for the prestation. There is the same presumption 
 when, in a disposition by gratuitous title, the beneficiary has been 
 charged with a prestation in favour of a third party, or when, by 
 a deed of transmission of a patrimony or of a transfer of a pro- 
 perty, a prestation in favour of a third party has been promised 
 by a transferee by way of family arrangement for the purpose of 
 rendering an equivalent (art. 330). 
 
 When the prestation to be made to a third party is to take place 
 upon the death of the person to whom the promise is made, the 
 third party is presumed, in case of doubt, to acquire a right to the 
 prestation upon the death of the person who received the promise. 
 If this person should die before the birth of the third party, 
 the promise to make a prestation to the third party specially 
 designed cannot be modified or revoked unless power to do so has. 
 been specially reserved (art. 331). 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 69 
 
 // the person who has received the promise has reserved to him- 
 self the power to substitute, without the consent of the promisor, 
 another person in place of the third person designated in the 
 contract, he may, likewise, in case of doubt, make this substitution 
 in a mortis causa disposition (art. 332). 
 
 // the third party intimates a repudiation of the right vested 
 in him under the contract the right is considered as not acquired 
 (art. 333). 
 
 Legal defences arising from the contract are available to the 
 promisor against the third party as well as against the stipulator 
 (art. 334). 
 
 The person who has received the promise may, likewise, unless 
 the contracting parties have manifested in the contract a contrary 
 intention, demand the execution of the prestation to the third 
 party, even when the right to this prestation belongs to the latter 
 (art. 335). 
 
 That is, the German Cade fully accepts the practical results 
 acquired by the jurisprudence, which are so important for the 
 business of insurance, but it does not attempt any theoretical 
 explanation of them, and it leaves the court a large discretion to 
 interpret the particular contract according to the intention of the 
 parties. 
 
 (See Windscheid, Vaivdekten, 8th ed. 2, s. 316, a.) 
 
 The language of the Egyptian codes rather suggests that the 
 legislator looked upon the stipulation pour autrui as a kind of 
 gestiou d'affaires. (137/198.) But it is not so definite as to 
 oblige the courts to accept this theory. 
 
 Characteristics of the third party's right. 
 
 The French Code and the Code of Quebec state expressly that 
 the right of the third Rarty is revoc able j>g_the stipulator until 
 it has been assented to by the third party. (C. C. F. 1121: 
 C. C. Q. 1029.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is silent upon this important point, but it 
 is safe to assume that the legislator did not mean to depart from 
 the French law on the subject. In France, it is held that the 
 exercise of this right of revocation is not subject to any particular J 
 form and may be implied. It is sufficient that the stipulator has 
 shown his intention to revoke. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 169; Agen, 
 8 mars 1893, in note to Cass. 10 dec. 1894, D. 1895. 1. 329.) 
 
 The revocation does not need the consent of the promisor, and 
 
70 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 its effect will usually be that the promisor is bound to make 
 payment to the stipulator instead of to the third party. 
 
 But this will not be so when the promisor can show that pay- 
 ment to the stipulator would be more onerous to him than payment 
 to the third party. For example, it is clear that if I give you 
 a farm on condition that you pay a life-rent to my father, my 
 revocation of the stipulation in his favour could not oblige you to 
 pay the life-rent to me for any period longer than my father's life. 
 
 The period must continue to be the length of my father's life 
 and not that of mine. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 523; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 170; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, n. 66. See Grenoble, 
 6 avril 1881, D. 82. 2. 9.) 
 
 fa And cases are conceivable in which the stipulation in favour of 
 a third party is o f so person al a Wind that it could not be rendered 
 to any one else. The substitution of the stipulator for the third 
 party would be clearly contrary to the original intention of the 
 parties. In such a case the revocation by the stipulator simply 
 relieves the promisor from the burden. (Aubry et Rau, 5th cd. 
 4, p. 523; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 170; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, 
 n. 68. See Guerette v. Ouellet, 1905, R. J. Q. 27 S. C. 45.) 
 
 If the stipulator dies before the third party has intimated his 
 assent, the heirs of the stipulator can exercise his right of re- 
 vocation unless this appears to be contrary to the intention of the 
 parties. The inchoate right of the third party created in his 
 favour without any participation by him can disappear in the 
 same manner and by the same procedure as that by which it came 
 into existence. 
 
 The right which the stipulator has to revoke the benefit which 
 his will has called into existence is an ordinary personal right, 
 which, on general principles, passes to his heirs. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 524; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 171; Douai, 10 dec. 
 1895, D. 96. 2. 417, and note by M. Dupuich; Bordeaux, 
 ler avril 1897, D. 98. 2. 169, and note by M. de Loynes.) 
 
 Some writers dispute this, and argue that the right of revocation 
 is essentially personal and is to be assimilated to the right to 
 revoke a gift on the ground of ingratitude, which by the French 
 law does not pass to the heirs of the donor. (C. C. F. 957; 
 Lambert, Contrat en faveur de Tiers, n. 90.) 
 
 But the weight of authority is in the other sense, and there 
 does not appear to be any reason why we should regard this right 
 as essentially personal. As M. Barde says, le Hers doit etre, au 
 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 71 
 
 regard des hSritiers du stipulant, dans la si inn lion ou il se trouvait 
 au regard du stipulant hd-meme; il conserve son droit, main, a 
 defaut d' acceptation, ce droit demeure aussi fragile qu'avant la 
 mort du stipulant. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 171.) 
 
 This, however, is a question of interpretation. In the case of _*> 
 life-assurance for the benefit of a third party, it is presumably 
 contrary to the intention of the assured that his heirs should have 
 the right to revoke the stipulation. The desire of the assured 
 is that the insurance-money shall not be a part of his succession, 
 and, although he reserves to himself the right to change its destina- 
 tion, he does not intend his heirs to have the same right. By 
 not exercising his right of revocation he has indicated that he does 
 not wish this money to go to his heirs. To allow them to revoke, 
 and in this way to secure for themselves what was meant for others, 
 would be to make the contract produce an effect entirely contrary 
 to what was intended. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 197; Aubry et Kau, 
 5th. ed. 4, p. 527; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 230; 
 D. N. C. C. 4, p. 928, n. 750.) 
 
 And although the heirs of the stipulator succeed to the right 
 to revoke the stipulation, except in the case of life-assurance, or > 
 where, in other cases, a contrary intention appears, this will not 
 be so when the stipulator in his will has confirmed the benefit 
 given to the third party, for this amounts to an interdiction of 
 the heirs from revoking the liberality. (Grenoble. 6 avril 1881, 
 D. 1882. 2. 9.) 
 
 The right to revoke the stipulation is however strictly personal 
 in the sense that if the stipulator does not choose to exercise it, 
 it cannot be exercised for him by his creditors. At any rate, this 
 is so in the case of insurance. The benefit conferred on the third 
 party is presumably conferred from motives of affection or family 
 interest. 
 
 The parties did not contemplate its revocation on purely 
 pecuniary grounds. It might be revoked for family considera- 
 tions and of these the stipulator was to be the sole judge. (Aubry 
 et Bau. 5th ed. 4, p, 212, note 48, Us; Dupuich, Assurance sur 
 la Vie, n. 212, Paris, 10 mars 1896, D. 96. 2. 465; note to D. 95. 
 2. 155, column 2, in fine. Contra, Douai, 10 dec. 1895, D. 96. 
 2. 417.) 
 
 The application of the rule is sufficiently clear in this case. It 
 may be less clear in other cases, but, although the question is one 
 of intention, it would seem that the right of revocation of a 
 benefit stipulated' for a third party is not as a general rule to be 
 
72 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 considered as being primarily a pecuniary claim or asset of the 
 stipulator's estate, such as his creditors are entitled to collect by 
 an action. (See the note by M. Dupuich to D. 96. 2. 417.) 
 
 Effects of assent. 
 
 >• tjf-S O It is generally agreed that the consequence of the assent is to 
 give to the third 'party a direct right of action against the promisor. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 72; Demolombe, 24, n. 255; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 529; Cass. 24 fevr. 1902, D. 1903. 1. 433; 
 D. N. C. C. ait. 1121, n. 122; C. A. Alex. 14 fevr. 1918. 
 B. L. J. XXX, 221.) 
 
 This is. after all, a matter of interpretation, and if considera- 
 tion of the contract leads to the conclusion that the parties never 
 intended to give a direct action to the beneficiary, there is no reason 
 why the court should refuse effect to this intention. 
 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 164; Cass. 20 dec. 1898, D. 99. 1. 320.) 
 The German Code leaves it for the court to decide if the third 
 party has a direct right (art. 328), and the Swiss Code says le tiers 
 ou ses ayants droit peuvent aussi reclamer personnellement 
 Vexecution, lorsque telle a ete Vintention des parties ou que tel 
 est Vusage. (Code Fed. des Oblig. art. 112.) 
 
 The stipulator has also an action to compel the promisor to 
 execute the stipulation in favour of the third party who has assented 
 to it, for it must not be forgotten that the promisor makes a direct 
 contract with the stipulator. (Demolombe, 24. nos. 232, 233: 
 B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 154; D. N. C. C. art. 1121, n. 144: Cass. 
 10 avril 1894, D. 99. 1. 270.) 
 
 It is because the stipulation for the third party is an integral 
 part of the contract that the third party enjoys the benefit of 
 all the guarantees, such as hypothecs, furnished by the promisor. 
 Whether the third party enjoys the privilege of the vendor is a 
 disputed point, which cannot here be adequately discussed. Many 
 writers deny it. But it seems reasonable to say with the 
 editors of the last edition of Aubry et Rau, une pareille charge 
 forme, en effet, partie du prix, dont Vintegralite se trouve gar an tie 
 par le privilege du vendeur, aux droits diiquel le beneficiaire de 
 oette charge se trouve virtuellement subroge. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 531, note 30; B.-L. et de Loynes, Nantissement, 
 n. 583; Caen, 24 avril 1902, D. 1904. 2. 425. Contra, B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 166.) Where an immoveable was sold subject 
 to a price in money and also to payment of an annuity to a : 
 
 (6 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 73 
 
 third party it was held by the court of Caen that this right to 
 the annuity was protected by the vendor's privilege. (Caen, 
 24 avril 1902, id su/p.) 'As a rule the stipulator does not bind 
 himself to any performance in favour of the third party. Accord- 
 ingly, the third party will have no action against him unless, in 
 the particular ease, he has specially bound himself. (B.-L. et 
 Barde, 1, n. 159; Cass. 6 juin 1880, D. 89. 1. 55.) 
 
 How may the third party declare his assent? 
 
 It is plain that since no form is prescribed, the assent may be 
 expressed or implied, and it is better to avoid the word "accept- 
 ance," though it is used in many of the cases, because it suggests 
 the theory which we have rejected that the third party is in the 
 position of a party to whom an offer is made. The rule that the 
 assent may be implied is supported by all French writers and by 
 many decisions. For instance, in a French case, where a sum 
 was to vest in a daughter either at her marriage, or on her setting 
 up a business, it was held that her assent was shown by her 
 commencing a business. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 172; Cass. 30 
 juill. 1877, D. 78. 1. 342. Cf. Bordeaux. 1 avril 1897, D. 
 98. 2. 169; D. N. C. C. art. 1121. n. 94.) 
 
 In particular, the bringing of an action by the beneficiary in 
 which he claims the execution of the stipulation is a sufficient in- 
 dication of his assent to it. (D. Rep. Oblig. n. 297; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1121, n. Ill; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 50; C. A. 
 Alex. 18 jam. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 163.) 
 
 f 1 
 If the legal representative of the third party is the stipulator 
 himself can he give the necessary assent for the third 
 party? 
 
 If a father insures his life for the benefit of a minor son, can 
 he, as his son's tutor, assent to the' stipulation for the son? Or 
 may we say that the assent is implied in the stipulation itself 
 which the father makes? It is not easy to answer affirmatively. 
 There are conflicting French decisions on this point. The view 
 of the Cow de Cassation is that the father may, in such a case/ 
 assent to the stipulation, but as this is a renunciation by him of 
 his right to revoke, his intention must be unequivocally shown. 
 It will not be implied from the mere fact of his signing the 
 policy in his own name and not on behalf of the son. (Cass. 25' 
 avril 1903, D. 1904. t. 150. But see Besangon, 11 nov. 1898, 
 
74 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 D. 99. 2. 81; note by Labbe, S. 89. 1. 290; B.-L. et Colin, 
 Donations, 1, n. 1293; Laurent, 12, n. 249; D. N. C. C. 4, 
 p. 922, n. 525; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 51; Lefort, 
 Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 106.) As M. Lambert says, this- 
 cannot be justified on the theory of the offer. It is, in effect, 
 saying that the acceptance by one of the parties of the offer made 
 by the other is sufficient to create a right not only in favour of 
 the stipulant but in favour of the third party. It is a subtilty 
 to attribute to the beneficiary an assent which really emanates 
 from the stipulator. (Contrat en faveur de Tiers, n. 97.) 
 
 A Quebec case is a good illustration. A sold a farm to B, 
 subject to a charge of a payment by B to C, who Avas a minor 
 child of A. 
 
 It was held no other assent was necessary. 
 
 The person who could have assented would have been A him- 
 self, as tutor for his minor child, and his assent was implied from 
 his making the stipulation. {Dostaler v. Dupont, 8 Quebec Law 
 Reports, 365.) 
 
 But if the stipulation by the father for the benefit of the 60ii 
 were assimilated to a donation, the father could not be both the 
 offeror and the acceptor. There would be no concourse of two 
 wills. (Laurent. 12, n. 249; B.-L. et Colin, Donations, 1, n. 
 1293.) And, unless we have the courage to say that in this case 
 no assent is required, it is difficult to justify such decisions. 
 (Lambert, 1. c.) 
 
 Assent does not need to be intimated to stipulator. 
 
 It is not necessaiy that the assent of the third party should be 
 intimated to the stipulator, or even to the promisor, in order to 
 render the third party's right irrevocable. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 528.) 
 
 It follows from what has been said that even when the stipula- 
 tion for the benefit of the third party is in effect a gift to him, 
 it does not need to be made or accepted in authentic form. 
 
 If the stipulation for the third party is the condition of an 
 onerous contract which one makes for oneself, the stipulation is 
 not subject to the formal rules applicable to ordinary gifts. The 
 stipulation for the third party is accessor}- to a contract which 
 does not need to be made in any special form. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, 
 n. 167; Req. 30 juill. 1877, D. 78. 1. 342.) 
 
 The German Code requires no assent on the part of the 
 
 > 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 75- 
 
 beneficiary. Unless he repudiates the benefit the right is acquired 
 (art. 333). 
 
 And the French jurisprudence is so liberal in admitting the 
 evidence of implied assent as almost to reach the same result. 
 (See Dupuich, Asmrance sur t la Vie, p. 129.) 
 
 Who can be a beneficiary under the stipulation? 
 
 There are three possible cases: (1) The third party who is to 
 benefit under the stipulation is a person individually designed 
 and actually living; [2 the stipulation is for the benefit of persons 
 who are living but indeterminate; (3 the stipulation is for the 
 benefit of future persons. 
 
 Determinate persons. 
 
 The person to benefit here is either mentioned by name in the 
 contract, or is indicated jii such a way as to leave no doubt as to 
 his identity. In the case of life-assurance, at any rate, it is 
 established in France that when the assured reserves, as he 
 generally does, the right to alter the beneficiary by an avenant or 
 annex to the policy, the position of the third party who is named 
 in this way is just the same as if he had been named in the policy 
 itself . The right of the beneficiary retroacts to the date of the 
 contract. (Cass. 19 nov. 1907, D. 1908. 1. 129, and Dissertation 
 by M. Dupuich; Lefort. Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 234.) 
 
 And, similarly, the beneficiary may be named in the course of 
 the life of the assured by an endorsement of the policy. (Cass. 
 4 mai 1904, D. 1905. 1. 165; "D. N. C. C. 4, p. 918, nos. 408 
 seq. and ib. Additions, 1913, p. 231, nos. 398 seq.) 
 
 Thus, to give an example: A husband insured his life for the 
 benefit of his wife. Subsequently the husband became bankrupt, 
 and a syndic or trustee for his creditors was appointed; thereafter 
 the assured died. The syndic claimed the insurance-money as 
 part of the bankrupt's estate. The Court of Appeal of Paris 
 held: (1) That the Avidow could accept the offer after her husband's 
 death; (2) That her acceptance retroacting to the date of the 
 insurance, she was vested in a personal and direct right against 
 the insurance-company which never formed a part of the estate 
 of the husband, and could only have entered into that estate if he 
 had used the right of revocation; and (3) That this right of 
 revocation, being a right strictly personal to the husband, could 
 
76 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 not be exercised by the syndic in his name. (Paris, 10 mars 
 1896, D. 96. 2. 465.) 
 
 And, according to the jurisprudence of the Cour de Cassation, 
 the result would have been precisely the same if the assurance had 
 been originally in favour of the assured and his heirs, and the 
 wife, or any other determinate person, had been substituted by 
 the assured in place of the heirs by an avenant to the policy. 
 (Cass. 7 aout 1888, S. 89. 1. 97, D. 88. 1. 118: B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 200; Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 234.) 
 
 Indeterminate or future persons. 
 
 Can a stipulation validly be made for the benefit of a person 
 not named, or even of a person not yet in existence? We have 
 seen that the prevailing theory now is that, under a stipulation 
 for the benefit of a third party, a right vests in the third party by 
 the effect of the contract. 
 
 Practical considerations make it eminently desirable to come 
 to this conclusion. But if the third party is as yet undeter- 
 mined, or does not yet exist, how is it possible to say that any 
 right is inherent in him? Can we conceive of a right which is 
 not inherent in any person, a right, that is to say, which no one 
 is entitled to enforce? In considering this question it is best to 
 distinguish indeterminate persons from future persons. 
 
 By indeterminate persons we mean those persons who are not 
 actually named or designated in the contract, but who, neverthe- 
 less, can be determined at the date when the contract is to take 
 effect for their benefit. A stipulation for the benefit of persons 
 who are not only indeterminate but indeterminable will certainlv 
 not be valid. But if, at the time when the contract is to take 
 effect, it is possible to make the determination, wlrv should we deny 
 effect to the stipulation? But assuming that the third party is 
 determinable, at the time when payment is demanded, although 
 not determinate at the date of the contract, is it possible to give 
 to this indeterminate person a droit propre from the date of the 
 contract itself? It is generally agreed that a legacy may be made 
 in favour of indeterminate persons if they are capable of being 
 made determinate later. 
 
 There is, of course, no difficulty when the legacy is made to a 
 determinate person in the first place, subject to the charge that 
 lie shall pay a certain sum to a person whom he shall select out of 
 a class named by the testator. (D. Snpp. vo. Dispositions enfrr 
 vifs, n. 842; D. N. C. C. art. 1002, n. 222.) 
 

 STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 77 
 
 For instance, if a yum is bequeathed to provide a dowry each 
 year for a poor and honest girl of a certain town, the girl' to bo ' 
 selected by the bishop, there is sufficient determination of the 
 legatee. (Caen, 9 juill. 1894, D. 95. 2. 236.) 
 
 And a legacy directly in favour of chacune des viugl villes de 
 France ayant le plus d'ouvrieres pauvres has been held to be valid 
 because, by inquiry, it could be determined which twenty towns 
 satisfied the condition. (Amiens, 26 fevr. 1879, S. 81. 2. 136; 
 Journal du Palais, 81, p. 708.) 
 
 If these results are correct, why should a different rule be applied 
 to the stipulation pour autrui? (Lambert, Contrat en favour de 
 Tiers, n. 133; Planiol, 2, n. 1236.) 
 
 But in the case of a legacy no right vests in the legatee until • 
 the death of the testator, whereas in the case of the stipulation' 
 pour autrui it is desired to find some means by which the right 
 can vest at once in the beneficiary, for, otherwise, it will be exposed 
 to the action of the creditors of the stipulator. Suppose, for 
 example, a man insures his life for the benefit of himself if he 
 survives a certain date, or of his heirs if he predeceases that date. 
 His heirs are not determinate at the date of the assurance, but 
 they will be determinate when he dies. 
 
 In the meantime, however, does any right vest in them? If it 
 does not it must vest in the assured himself and form part of his 
 patrimony . And if he dies insolvent his creditors will be entitled 
 to take the sum paid by the insurance-company. 
 
 The French authorities are in favour of the right of the creditors 
 in this case. (Lyons, 9 avril 1878, D. 79. 2. 158; Besangon, 
 14 mars 1883, D. 83. 2. 129; Cases in note to Paris, 8 juill. 
 1904, D. 1906. 2. 13, and in D. N. C. C. 4, p. 919, nos. 427 
 seq. ; Cass. 20 d&6 : . 1876, D. 77. 1. 504; Dupuich, Assurance sur 
 la Vie, n. 194.) Other expressions which have been held to denote 
 personnes indeterminees are mes parents, mes cousins, and even 
 mes enfants nes ou a naitre. (As to the last see infra, p. 82 seq., 
 and Dissertation by M. Dupuich in D. 1906. 2. 13; Lefort, Traite 
 du Contrat d'Assuranae sur la Vie, 2, p. 138.) 
 
 But why is it necessary to come to this conclusion? It is 
 presumably contrary to the intention of the parties. 
 
 The assured may be presumed to have intended that the 
 insurance-money should not form part of his succession. At least 
 such a presumption is reasonable when, at the date of the in- 
 surance his heirs are his wife and children, and, in an Egyptian 
 
78 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 case, the Mixed Court of Appeal has held that in this case it is 
 possible to g-ive effect to his intention. 
 
 En cos de predeces de Vassure, la somme appartient done aux 
 heritiers naturels et ne pent pas etre consideree comme line depend- 
 ance de sa succession soumise a V action des creanciers ; il importe 
 pen que les beneficiaires eventuels de Vassurance n'aient pas ete 
 nommement designes dans le contrat, du moment que tant au 
 moment du contrat qa'a celui du deces, les heritiers naturels de 
 Vassure se trouvaient etre sa femme et ses en f ants tons nes au 
 moment du contrat et v'wants lors du deces. (C. A. Alex. 28 nov. 
 1901, B.L.J. XIV, 27. Cf . C. A. Alex. 27 avril 1904, B.L.J. 
 XVI, 217. See Cass. 2 juillet 1884, D. 85. 1. 150; and the note 
 to Paris, 8 juillet 1904, D. 1906. 2. 13; and see infra, p. 82.) 
 In the case decided by the Court of Paris the expression in the 
 policy was heritiers directs, and the court held that the assured 
 intended by this phrase to denote his minor children existing at 
 the date of the contract. 
 
 The Mixed Court in Egypt and the Court of Paris recognise 
 that persons actually existing at the date of the insurance may_ 
 acquire a direct right, though they are not named in the policy,. 
 But can we go further and say that such a direct right can be 
 created in favour of a person actually indeterminate and indeter- 
 minable at the date of the contract? 'There is no doubt that this 
 result would best satisfy the requirements of business, but the 
 difficult}" is to find a satisfactory legal ground upon which to rest 
 it. It is perhaps possible to accept the solution adopted by some 
 French writers. 
 
 Cases where beneficiary is indeterminable at date of contract. 
 
 But before stating this- theory it is well to point out that there 
 are several cases in which it is generally admitted that a stipula- 
 tion is valid, though at the date of the contract it is not possible 
 to sslj who the third party is for whom the benefit is stipulated. 
 The jurisprudence in France has in these cases clearly recognised 
 the possibility of a valid stipulation for an indeterminate person. 
 
 Thus, in marine-insurance, the usual form of policy is pour le 
 compte de qui il appartiendra. 
 
 The assurer is -bound not only to the present owner of the goods 
 but also to any future owner. L' assurance pour compte de qui il 
 appartiendra cree un lien de droit, non settlement entre les parties 
 demommees au contrat, mais encore entre Vassureur et les pro- 
 prietmres presents et futurs de la chose assuree. 
 
 ,r 
 
 ■ 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 79 
 
 The person in right of the bill of lading is entitled to claim the 
 benefit of the contract. (Cass. 27 juin 1899, S. 1903. 1. 502; 
 Amiens, 10 juin 1887, D. 89. 2. 177: Cass. 5 mars 1888, D. 
 88. 1. 366, S. 88. 1. 315; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Trcdie de 
 Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 6, n. 1192. Cf . Arnould on Marine 
 Insurance, 7th ed. 2, s. 1279.) 
 
 One cannot say at the date of the contract who will have the 
 right of suing the "underwriter," as the marine insurer is called. 
 
 The English form is that the assured makes the contract " as 
 well in his own name as for and in the name and names of all 
 and every person or persons to whom the same doth, may, or 
 shall appertain." (Arnould on Marine Insurance, 7th ed. 1, 
 s. 12.) 
 
 Again, before the French loi du 9 avril 1898. which gave to 
 workmen in industrial occupations a right to compensation for 
 death or bodily injury caused by accidents during their work, 
 without proof of fault on the part of the emplo} r er, it was common 
 for the employer to insure his workmen against industrial acci- 
 dents. Such contracts took various forms, but the most usual was 
 the form called in France assurance-collective. Under this form 
 of contract the employer insured his workmen against the pro- 
 fessional risk collectively and without their participation, and 
 made a deduction from their wages towards the payment of the 
 premiums. According to the prevailing jurisprudence in France, 
 this gives to an injured workman or to the representatives of a 
 workman who has been killed by an accident during the work a 
 direct right of action against the insurance-company. (D. N. 
 C. C. 4, p. 935, nos. 82 seq.; Lambert, Du Contrat en fare/ti- 
 de Tiers, n. 280. Cf. Pau, 30 juin 1913, D. 1915. 2. 49.) 
 
 In many cases this result has been justified upon the ground 
 that the employer acts as negotiorum gestor for the workmen, 
 and that they ratify his acts by agreeing to the deduction from 
 their wages to meet the premiums. It is this which creates the 
 lien de droit between the workmen and the insurance-company. 
 (Paris, 22 juill. 1897, D. 98. 2. 94; Trib. Civ. de Morlaix. 2 
 juin 1915, D. 1916. 2. 29.) 
 
 But a more correct view appears to be that this is an example 
 of stipulation pour autrui. The employer continues bound to 
 pay the premiums; he does not intend to contract in the name of 
 the workmen who vary from day to day, and he has no intention 
 to offer to them the right to take over the engagement which he 
 has mad.'. There is no real analogy between this case and that of 
 
 
80 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 gestion d'affaires. (Lambert, op. <il. n. 289; Douai, 11 juill. 
 1895, D. 97. 2. 369; and note by M. Dupuich. 
 
 But if this is the correct solution, it is clear that we have here 
 another example of a right being created in favour of a person 
 not determinate at the date of the contract. Nothing can be 
 more variable or uncertain than the personnel of an industry. 
 The employer does not know at the date of the insurance how 
 many of the men whom he has at that moment in his employment 
 will be there six months hence. The workmen who may be in- 
 jured during the course of the year may have been in the employ- 
 ment at the date of the policy, or may have entered the employ- 
 ment at any time during its course, and perhaps on the day before 
 the accident. This is immaterial to the employer and to the 
 insurance-company. It is the group of workmen, generally 
 defined as not exceeding a certain number, which is insured. 
 Nothing tan be more indeterminate . And it is the same when an 
 employer contracts with a doctor to give medical attendance to 
 his workmen. (Pau, 30 juin 1913, D. 1915. 2. 49.) 
 
 Similarly, the clauses made in favour of the workmen in a 
 contract between a public authority and a contractor, are in favour 
 of persons as yet entirely indeterminate, and, nevertheless, a direct 
 right is given to the workmen. (Paris, 8 fevr. 1908, D. 1908. 2. 
 185.) 
 
 And the same applies to contracts of public utility where they 
 are considered to give direct rights to the inhabitants of a parti- 
 cular locality, and to the beneficiaries under a charitable founda- 
 tion created by an acte entre vifs to be administered by a muni- 
 cipality or other moral person. (See Planiol, 2, n. 1237.) 
 
 Future persons. 
 
 From what has been said, it is clear, that there is no great 
 difficulty in holding that a right may be created in favour of a 
 person not determinate if that person was actually existing at 
 the date of the contract- Is it possible to apply the same rule to 
 "future persons," that is to say, to persons who did not exist at 
 the date of the contract? This is a much more difficult question. 
 It is clear that I cannot make a contract with a poison not yet in 
 existence, but can I in a contract which I make with another, 
 stipulate a benefit for a person who is not yet in existence? 
 
 If we were to accept the theory of the offer as the explanation 
 of the stipulation pour autrui the answer would clearly need to 
 be in the negative, for it is impossible to make an offer to a person 
 
 ;- 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 81 
 
 not in existence. We have, however, rejected the theory of the 
 offer, and this difficulty does not stand in the way, but how is.it 
 possible that a right can exist which is not inherent in any subject, 
 that is to say, which no one is entitled to enforce? Must not 
 every droit have a titulatie and belong to some patri m omc ? Can 
 there be a right which is, so to speak, floating in the air? These 
 questions have been keenly discussed by French writers. 
 
 The question is a very practical one. If a man insures his life 
 for the benefit of his wife and children he does not know how many 
 children may be born to him. Nor, as a rule, if he has children 
 already, does he mean to make any distinction between these 
 children already born at the date of the policy and those who 
 may be born afterwards. 
 
 But if the law does not allow a stipulation for the benefit of a 
 future person, he cannot in this way provide for the unborn chil- 
 dren. By a legal technicality we defeat a most laudable intention. 
 
 The French courts have in fact gone so far as to hold that when 
 the insurance is in favour of enfants nes et a naitre neither the 
 children already born nor the children subsequently born acquire 
 a droit propre at the date ( of the policy. (Besangon, 23 dec. 1891, 
 D. 92. 2. 111.) And the Court of Cassation holds that it is a 
 question of interpretation whether the father intended in the same 
 disposition to assure an equal sum to his children born or unborn, 
 and if the Court of Appeal has found that this was his intention 
 the Court of Cassation must accept this finding. (Cass. 7 mars 
 1893, D. 94. 1. 77; D. N. C. C, 4, p. 920, nos. 476 seq.) 
 
 As it would be shocking to create inequality among the children 
 whom the father intended to benefit equally, and as the unborn 
 children could acquire no droit propre at the date*of the policy, 
 equality is to be restored by giving a right to none of them. The 
 result is that where the policy is in these terms no right vests 
 in any of the children; the claim to the insurance money is part 
 of the father's succession, and if he dies insolvent the capital goes 
 to his creditors. (Amiens, 19 juin 1901, D. 1903. 5. 58.) 
 
 It is no wonder that the writers in France struggle against a 
 conclusion so inequitable. (Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 74; 
 Lambert, Du Contrat en favour de Tiers, nos. 138 seq.; Lefort, 
 Assurance sur la Vie., 2, pp. 250, 256.) 
 
 Is it to be admitted that the law forbids a father to provide 
 for his unborn children, and that a man can by an insurance on 
 his life make a provision for a complete stranger, whose only 
 merit is that he is already existing, while he cannot provide for 
 
 \V — VOL II 6 
 
 7 eW; 
 
82 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 his own children? A> M. Lambert says: on ne pent pas ne pas se 
 defter de V exactitude et de la legalite d'un principe qui conduit 
 a de pareils resultats. (Op. c-it. n. 139, in fin. And M. Labbe 
 says: le legislateur doit se hater de modifier ime legislation pen 
 hospitaliere pour une institution aussi morale, aussi bienfaisante 
 que I'o >sn ranee sur la vie, surtout quand elle est contract ee, avec 
 une abnegation genereuse, par une personne au profit direct de 
 ses enfants nes et a uaiire.) (Note to Cass. 2 juill. 1884, S. 85. 
 1 . 8, in fine. Cf. M. Labbe in note to Douai, 6 dec. 1886, S. 88. 
 ■J. J97. And. lastly. M. Lefort says: It convient, dans rinteret 
 meme du developpement de Vassurance sur la vie, de lutter avee 
 energie pour I 'iw iter les cas ou V attribution devra etre consideree 
 faite en faveur de tiers indetermines. 11 importe d'obtenir que 
 Von an.gmente le cas ou le droit propre pourra etre reconnu, afin 
 de. permetirv pour la farniUe la constitution d'une reserve a Vabri 
 des vicissitudes causees par la mort de son chef. Assurance sur 
 J a Vie, 2. p. 256., 
 
 This last writer is afraid that it is too late to maintain in France 
 that a stipulation merely in favour of heritiers ou an ants droit 
 should be interpreted as conferring a vested right in the sum 
 promised. The term " heirs " suggests that the assured was think- 
 ing of the beneficiaries in the light of his legal successors wh& 
 continue his personality. It is true he m.ay have been thinking of 
 those persons who when he made the contract happened to be his 
 heirs presumptive, and as events turned out were his heirs and 
 his only heirs at the time of his death. 
 
 On the other hand, he may have been thinking of the benefi- 
 ciaries as those persons at present unknown to him who at his 
 death would be his heirs. 
 
 But in either case the result will be the same, for it is precisely 
 in their character of heirs that the beneficiaries will be entitled to 
 claim the insurance money. They will take it jure hcereditario 
 and not jure sub. It seems to me that in the first of the.e two 
 eases M. Lefort admits too 'much. If at the date of the policy the 
 heirs presumptive of the assured were his wife and childrn, and 
 the insurance is for himself if he is living at a certain date, or 
 otherwise for his heirs, is it not a reasonable presumption that 
 when he speaks in the policy of his " heirs " he is thinking of his 
 wife and children as individuals and not of a group of persons who 
 may happen to be his heirs at his death? 
 
 As we have seen, this view lias been taken by the Mixed Court 
 of Appeal m one ease. ;C. A. Alex. 23 nov. 1901, B. L. J. 
 XIV, 27; supra, p. 77. in fine.) 1 \ 
 
 * 
 
STIPULATION FOB THE BENEFIT OP THIRD PARTIES. 83 
 
 But even if we are to admit that whore the stipulation is for 
 the benefit of "heirs"' or ayants cause, no droit propre is created, 
 at any rate, unless there are very special reasons for supposing thai 
 the word "heirs" -was meant to describe particular individuals, 
 it is surely unnecessary to go as far as the French courts have 
 gone in denying the creation of a droit propre when tho stipula- 
 tion is for the benefit of "children. 
 
 If a father insures his life for the benefit of his children, it is 
 entirely unreasonable to presume that he intended the insurance 
 money to go to his heirs as such, and therefore, possibly, to. his 
 creditors, seeing that the object of the insurance in almost every 
 case is precisely to create a distinct fund for the benefit of the 
 persons named which shall not be a part of his succession and shall 
 be protected from the creditors. 
 
 If the assured had not intended to create such a fund why should 
 lie insure for the benefit of " children " at all? The result would 
 have been the same if the insurance had been for his own benefit 
 alone. 
 
 In France the jurisprudence has become so established that 
 some writers think it is vain to contend for the validity of a stipu- 
 lation in favour of future persons. They admit with regret that 
 an insurance for the benefit of enfants a nmtre cannot give these 
 a vested right, because the jurisprudence is quite settled in the 
 contrary sense. All that they fight against is the jurisprudence 
 to the effect that when the stipulation is for the benefit of enfants 
 ties et a naitre it should be invalid as regards the children existing 
 at the date of the contract. (Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 2, 
 p. 258.) 
 
 But in countries, like Egypt, which have a law based upon the 
 French system, but where the courts are not bound to follow the 
 French jurisprudence, we may certainly go further, and maintain 
 that, upon the principles of the French law, there is no impossi- 
 bility in giving a droit propre to a future person. It is necessary, 
 therefore, to examine the grounds upon which the French juris- 
 prudence rests. They appear to be mainly two: (1) A person 
 not yet born or conceived cannot succeed as an heir whether on 
 intestacy or by will, and cannot receive a gift, and the same reasons 
 prevent a future person from taking a benefit in this way under 
 a stipulation. (2) It is impossible to conceive of a right not 
 inherent in any subject. 
 
 As regards the right of succession the reason why the French 
 
 6 (2) 
 
84 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 law excludes future persons is because it accepts the principle 
 laid down as to saisine in the old adage le mort misit le : vii. 
 (Planiol, 3, n. 1931; Colin et Capitant, 3, pp. 444 seq.) 
 
 There must be an immediate and direct transmission of the 
 succession from the deceased to the heir. 
 
 We must seek for a man's heirs at the moment when the suc- 
 cession opens, and we cannot admit into the class of heirs any 
 person who is not there at that date. (C. C. F. 725.). As regards 
 the capacity to take a gift, a future person is excluded for the 
 plain reason that a gift is a contract, and that a contract requires 
 two parties. As the future person, ex hypothesi, has no existence 
 ho cannot accept a gift, nor. can any one accept on his behalf . 
 (C. C. F. 906.) 
 
 But the French law has always admitted that when there was 
 a direct gift to one person subject to a charge in favour of another 
 person, this second person did not need to be in existence at the 
 date of the contract; in fact any other rule would make charitable 
 foundations impossible. (Caen, 15 nov. 1906, D. 1907. 2. 265. 
 See Planiol, 3, nos. 3330 seq.) But by the French law, where 
 there is a direct gift, it must be to some person having capacity, 
 and not to a group of persons not recognised as having legal 
 personality such as, for example, an association like a peace society 
 which has no corporate existence. (Paris, 18 fevr. 1909, D. 
 1909. 2. 273.) 
 
 And the whole law of substitutions, so important in France 
 before the Code Napoleon so greatly restricted their use, rests 
 upon the principle that it is not necessary that the substitute should 
 exist at the time of the gift, if he exists and is capable of taking 
 when the substitution opens in his favour. (C. C. F. 896, 1048; 
 Pothier, Traite des Donations entre Vifs, n. 105.) 
 
 But when, instead of a gift to A for the benefit of B, we have 
 a direct gift to B, and B is a future person, is it possible to say 
 that a right in favour of B is created by the contract? This leads 
 to the consideration of (2) which is the crux of the problem. 
 
 The French courts which deny this possibility have no doubt 
 been influenced by the theory of the offer. If the stipulation 
 pour autrui is regarded as an offer to the third party, it is essential 
 that the offer shall be to an existing person. (Lambert, Du 
 Contrat en faveur de Tiers, n. 140.) 
 
 But, rejecting the theory of the offer, is it still impossible to 
 give a right to a non-existing person? Seeing that the assent of 
 the third party is not necessary to create the right why is it neces- 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 85 
 
 sary that he should exist in order that the right should be created? 
 The stipulation cannot give the third party before his conception 
 a vested right, but it is not necessary that the contract should 
 produce its effect immediatelj' . The third party finds when he 
 is born an expectancy or eventual right which was only waiting 
 for his birth in order to take shape. 
 
 The promisor is bound to the beneficiary when he is born, just 
 as in the case of collective insurance the insurance-company is 
 bound to the workman of whose existence it had no knowledge at 
 the date of the contract, or the gas-company, or water-company, 
 in the case of the contracts of public utility, is liable to the house- 
 holder whether he was born or not at the date of the contract. In 
 support of this argument an analogy may be drawn from the law 
 of sale. There can be a valid contract of sale of a future thing 
 though the sale can produce no immediate effect, and will indeed 
 never produce any effect unless the future thing conies into 
 existence . 
 
 The operation of the contract is suspended until we see if there 
 w.as in fact any object sold, and, if it turns out that there was, the 
 sale is valid. 
 
 If there can be, as in this case, a valid contract before we know 
 whether there is an object, why can there not be a valid contract 
 before we know whether there is a subject? This analogy was 
 already made by Ranchin who died in 158f3. Et sicuti spes rei 
 qua speratur facit valere stipulationem ; ita spes persona qua 
 speratur facit valere talem donationem. (Sur la question 267 de 
 Guy-Pape.) 
 
 It has been approved of by many writers. (Lambert, Du 
 Contrat en faveur de Tiers, n. 189; Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 
 2, p. 254; Planiol, 2, n. 1242.) 
 
 The question is so delicate that I will, at the risk of repetition, 
 quote the language of M. Lambert, which M. Lefort adopts. 
 
 Assurement la stipulation ne pent pas confer er an tiers avant 
 sa conception un droit defvnitivement acquis ; mms ce tiers trouve, 
 le jour ou il vient au monde un droit eventuel qui nattendait 
 que sa naissance pour prendre corps, ti qui pouvait tenir debout 
 sans son intervention, parceqiCil sortait d'un contrat valablemerit 
 forme entre deux autres personnes. On pent stipuler au profit 
 d'une personne future comme on pent stipuler une chose future. 
 (Lambert, I.e.) 
 
 Although the merit of simplicity can certainly not be claimed 
 for this theory, and difficult as it is to conceive of a right, which is, 
 
86 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 so to speak, floating in the air until some person comes into 
 existence entitled to claim it, this is, nevertheless, perhaps the 
 only theory upon which the decisions of the courts can be sup- 
 ported. As we have seen, there are quite a number of cases in 
 which the courts have consistently found that a droit propre was 
 created by the contract, although it was impossible at its date to 
 say who the beneficiary was, and, as a matter of fact, the benefi- 
 ciary might not be at that time in existence. 
 
 In tlu i case of a contract of public utility, such as that between 
 a municipality and a gas-company, the right created in favour of 
 the householders does not seem to depend on their existence at the 
 date of the contract. 
 
 Many owners of property within the municipality may be 
 children who were born after the date of the contract, but their 
 right to enforce the contract would seem to be as good as that of 
 anv other of the inhabitants. 
 
 Matter dealt with in many countries by legislation. 
 
 As regards insurance for the benefit of unborn children there 
 has been in many countries legislation. 
 
 Thus in England, by the Married Women's Property Act y 
 1882, the husband or wife may insure for the benefit of his or 
 her children. 45 & 46 Vict. c. 75, s. 11. See Laws of England, 
 vo. Husband and Wife, v. 16, p. 399. Cf. Revised Statutes, 
 Quebec, art. 5581; and, for a note of similar legislation in other 
 countries, see Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 227; Code Comm. 
 Ital. art. 453; Giorgi, Obbligazioni, 3, p. 577. 
 
 In the English law such a policy creates a trust in favour of 
 the objects therein named, and so long as any object of the trust 
 remains unperformed, the moneys payable under the policy do 
 not form part of the estate of the insured. The term "wife" 
 includes a second wife, and the term "children" includes the 
 children of a second marriage unless a contrary intention appears 
 in the policy. [Parker's PoUcies, In re, 1906, 1 Ch. 526, 75 
 L. J. Ch. 297: Griffith's Policy, In re, 1903, 1 Ch. 739, 72 
 L. J. Ch. 330.) 
 
 The difficulty at present in the French law arises from the 
 language of the code. If the law were amended by an express 
 provision declaring that a direct right could be given to a third 
 party even though indeterminate or unborn, there would be no 
 further difficultv. This ought to be done. 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 87 
 
 Rights of creditors in the case of insurance for a third party. 
 
 If a third party has acquired a droit pmprc upon the principles 
 which have been explained, the creditors of the assured, even if 
 he dies in a state of insolvency, cannot claim the insurance-money, 
 because, according to the theory, it never formed a part of his 
 estate. (Grenoble, 11 d6c. 1894, D. 96. 2. 97; Cass. 2 aout 
 1909, D. 1910. 1. 328; Dupuich, Assarai/rr sur la Vie, n. 222. y 
 
 Nor can the creditors, as a general rule, claim that the third 
 party shall restore to them the amount of the premiums -which the 
 assured paid. 
 
 They_can do so only when they can show that the payments were 
 in fraud of their rights. C. ('. E. 143 204: C. C.F. 1107. 
 
 If they can show that the payment of the premiums was a 
 fraudulent alienation of the kind challengeable by the Paulian 
 action, they can claim their return from the beneficiary, but this 
 will not often be the case. So long as the management of his 
 affairs has not been withdrawn from the debtor, he can deal freely 
 with his income, and it is only alienations of capital which his 
 creditors can challenge. [Dissert ait on by M. Boistel, in note to 
 Nancy, 17 janv. 1888, D. 89. 2. 157; Paris. 10 mars 1896, D. 
 96. 2. 465; Lefort, Assurance sur la Vie, 2, p. 241. Cf. Cass. 
 2 aout 1909, D. 1910. 1. 328.) 
 
 What is the effect of the rescission of a contract in which a 
 benefit was stipulated for a third party who has assented 
 to it? 
 
 If the contract between the stipulator and the promisor was 
 null or is rescinded, does the third party who assented to the 
 benefit lose his right? JWj^ep the contract was null ah initio, 
 there can be little doubt that he does. The right of the third 
 party flows from the contract, although he was not a party to it," 
 and if there was no valid contract from the beginning he could 
 have no right under it. Accordingly, if the contract is declared 
 to be void on account of the want of capacity of the promisor, or 
 on account of defect of form, the right of the third party must 
 fall with it. And, further, if the contract was valid ab initio 
 but is afterwards annulled at the instance of the promisor on the 
 ground of force, or error, or fraud, the third party will likewise 
 lose his right. 
 
 For example, in a Canadian case, a policy of life-assurance was 
 effected for the benefit of a creditor, of the assured. 
 
88 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The policy was afterwards declared null and void on the ground 
 that the assured had made false representations as to his state of 
 health. It was held that the nullity could be invoked against the 
 third party who was named as the beneficiary under the policy. 
 (Venner v. Life Insurance Company, 1889, 17 Canadian Supreme 
 Court Reports, 394. See Pmd. Franc, vo. Oblig. n. 7354.) 
 
 But if the stipulator himself brings an action for the resolution 
 or revocation of the contract and is successful, does this deprive 
 the third party of his droit acquis ? This is a controversial 
 question. Suppose I sell you a. farm for a certain price, and 
 stipulate in addition that you shall pay an annuity to my father. 
 My father assents to the stipulation for his benefit. You fail 
 to pay the price. Under the French and Egyptian codes in the 
 sale of immoveables as well as of moveables the unpaid vendor 
 has the right of action in dissolution of the sale. (C. C. E. 
 332/413; C. C. F. 1654; Halton, 2, p. 56.) 
 
 Accordingly, I bring an action for dissolution of the sale and 
 get judgment in my favour. Has my father any claim against 
 me or against you or does his right simply fall to the ground? 
 
 It is generally agreed that if when you are sued you do not have 
 my father rmsjm^cause, the judgment cannot affect him, according 
 to the rule res inter alios acta aliis non nocet. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 531; Demolombe, 24. n. 258; Pond . Franc. Oblig. 
 nos. 7525—7530; Cass. 6 juin 1888, D. 89. 1. 55.) 
 
 But we will suppose that my father has been made a party to 
 the action. According to the view supported by most of the 
 French writers, even in this case, my father's claim to the annuity 
 is still good. They contend that by his assent to the stipulation 
 in his favour he acquired an irrevocable right of which the 
 stipulator cannot deprive him by obtaining the rescission of the 
 contract. 
 
 But the French writers do not agree as to whether my father's 
 right in the case supposed would be against me or against you. 
 According to one system when (lie contract is rescinded, you, 
 the promisor, have no further liability, but I, the stipulator, am 
 bound in favour of my father because I allowed him to acquire a 
 vested right. (Aubry et Rau, I.e.) 
 
 According to another system, you, the promisor, are still bound 
 
 to my father, but you will have a right of indemnity against me, 
 
 the stipulator. (B.-L. et Bardc, 1, n. 174.) 
 
 >^ Another view which has less support is that the effect of the 
 
 rescission of the contract is to restore the parties to the status 
 
 i 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 89 
 
 in quo ante, and that the right of the third party must fall with 
 the contract out of which it flows. His right is accessory in 
 character, and its existence depends upon the validity of the con- 
 tract. By calling it irrevocable the French Code only means that 
 the stipulator has lost his right to revoke it so long as the prin- 
 cipal contract is still in existence. He cannot maintain the 
 contract for himself, and revoke it as regards the third party. 
 But if the contract itself is rescinded, there is no basis on which 
 the right of the third party can rest. Consequently, neither the 
 promisor nor the stipulator is bound to the third party, and if 
 the promisor has already paid him anything he can claim repeti- 
 tion of it, for otherwise, the restitutio in integrum would not be 
 complete. (Larombiere, art. 1121, n. 10.) 
 
 This latter view that the third party's right depends on a valid 
 contract has been adopted by the German Code, and it seems to 
 me to be more logical than the opinion which has found greater 
 favour in France. 
 
 Les moyens de defense resultant du control appartiennent au 
 promettunt egalement a Vencontre du tiers,. 
 
 (art. 334. See Windscheid, Pandekten, 8th ed. 2, s. 316 a, 
 p. 287.) 
 
 Comparison with English law. 
 Common law as to the persons affected by contract. 
 
 Leaving out of sight the relation of principal and agent and 
 the rights and liabilities of heirs and successors, the common law 
 adheres very strictly to the rule that a person who is not a party 
 to a contract cannot either sue or be sued upon it. (Pollock on 
 Contracts, 8th ed. p. 208; Anson on Contracts, 14th ed. p. 272.) 
 
 A contract between A and B cannot impose a liability upon C 
 except in the sense that if C, out of malice, induces A or B to 
 break the contract he commits a tort. But this is not an obliga- 
 tion under the contract. (See, as to this last point, Quinn v. 
 Leathern, 1901, A. C. 495, 70 L. J. P. C. 76; Boiven v. Hall, 
 1881, 6 Q. B. D. 333, 50 L. J. Q. B. 305; and cf. in France, 
 Paris, 24 nov. 1904, S. 1905. 2. 284.) 
 
 Nor can a contract confer a right on a third party to enforce the 
 contract, though the parties expressly declare that it shall do so. 
 {Tweddle v. Atkinson, 1861, 1 B. & S. 393, 30 L. J. Q. B. 265. 
 124 K. K. 610; Leake on Contracts, 6th ed. p. 296; Pollock on 
 Cmtr acts, 8th ed. p. 222.) 
 
90 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 In the English law there is no exception to these rules, which 
 are regarded as flowing from the mere conception of contract, 
 unless it is correct to regard as an exception the rule of equity by 
 which unborn children may acquire rights under a marriage settle- 
 ment as being, in the language of the English law, ''within the 
 consideration of marriage." (See Gale v. Gale, 1877, 6 Ch. D. 
 144, 46 L. J. Ch. 809; Be Cameron and Wells, 1887. 37 Ch. D. 
 32, 57 L. J. Ch. 69. 
 
 But a marriage settlement has much of the nature of a trust, 
 and, probably in all systems of law, different rules apply to it from 
 those which apply to ordinary contracts. 
 
 The rigorous doctrine of the common law is to some extent 
 mitigated by certain statutory exceptions, especially by the 
 Married Women's Property Act, 1882, already referred to, which 
 allows a husband or wife to insure for the benefit of children, 
 and gives to the beneficiary a direct action. (45 & 46 Vict. c. 70. 
 s . 11; supra, p . 86 . 
 
 And the inconveniences of the doctrine are considerably miti- 
 gated by the law of trusts. A trust in the sense of the English 
 law of equity means that one person who is called the trustee has 
 lights which he is bound to exercise upon behalf of another, or 
 for the accomplishment of some particular purpose. When, as 
 is usually the case, the trust is created by an agreement between 
 the truster and the trustee, we have a situation analogous to the 
 stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 Some English authorities, indeed, are inclined to regard a trust 
 as a real exception to the rule of the relativity of contracts. It 
 is true that the majority of trusts, though not all of them, arise 
 out of a contract between the creator of the trust and the trustee. 
 
 But the better opinion is that trust and contract are quite 
 distinct things. A contract has for its sole object to create obliga- 
 tions, whereas a trust may have many other objects. (See Mail- 
 land, Equity, p. 53; Snell, Equity, 17th ed. p. 44; Pollock, 
 Contracts, 8th ed. p. 219; Anson. Contracts, 14th ed. p. 272.) 
 
 The English trust has been described as "perhaps the most 
 distinctive achievement of English lawyers," and it has many 
 peculiarities which distinguish it from a contract. (See Maitland, 
 op. cit. p. 23: Anson, I.e. 
 
 And, although no formal words are necessary for the creation of 
 a twist, nevertheless, if a trust is to lie created in favour of a third 
 party, it is not enough that one of the parties should promise to 
 
STIPULATION FOR THE BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. 91 
 
 pay money to a third party, there must be words amounting to a 
 declaration of a trust. An imperfect gift is not a declaration of 
 trust. 
 
 Cf. Richard* v. DelbrUge, 1874, L. P. 18 Eq. 11, 43 
 L. J. Ch. 459; Murray v. Flavell 1883, 25 Ch. D. 89. 53 
 L. J. Ch. 185. See Maitland, op. ait. p. 74.; 
 
 American law less rigorous as to relativity of contracts. 
 
 It is interesting to notice that in the United States there is a 
 decided tendencj' to moderate the rigour of the English law as 
 to the relativity of contracts, and to approach more nearly to the 
 French law of stipulation pour autrui. For example, in many 
 States a beneficiary of a life-insurance policy is given a right to- 
 enforce the policy, and that without the aid of any statute, and 
 there are other illustrations of the same tendency which cannot 
 here be referred to. (See the chapter by Mr. S. Williston on 
 " Contracts for the Bonefit of a Third Person in the United States."' 
 in Pollock, Contracts, 3rd American ed. pp. 237 seq.) 
 
 The English trust has many advantages, and. as Maitland says. 
 "seems to us almost essential to civilization.'" The want in the 
 civil law of anything which answers quite the same purpose 
 appears to English lawyers to be the greatest defect of that system . 
 (See the remarks of F. W. Maitland in 'Collected Papers," in 
 index under "Trust.") 
 
$2 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTORS RIGHTS AND 
 ACTIONS BY HIS CREDITORS. 
 
 The French Code, after laying down the broad rale that agree- 
 ments cannot affect anybody but the parties to them, with the 
 exception of the case where there has been a stipulation pour 
 autrui, proceeds to give, as further exceptions or qualifications of 
 the general rule: 
 
 (1) That, nevertheless, creditors may exercise all the rights and 
 -actions of their debtor, with the -exception ofmichas are exclusivehj 
 attached to the person ; and 
 
 (2) That creditors may also in their own name attack the acts 
 executed by their debtor in fraud of their rights. (C. C. F. 
 1166—1167.) 
 
 In the first case the creditors bring what is often called the 
 oblique or indirect action, and in the second they bring the direct 
 auction, or, as it is generally called, the Paulian action. As a 
 matter of arrangement this is unsatisfactory. When creditors act 
 in the debtor's place they act in his name and on his account, and 
 cannot, therefore, properly be regarded as third parties. And when 
 they bring the Paulian action and attack their debtor's contract, 
 they are not third parties either, or, at any rate, they are third 
 parties only in a very special sense. It may be said that in 
 attacking their debtor's contract they maintain that by making 
 it the debtor exceeded his powers of administration of an estate 
 in which they have an interest, and that, although, in general, he 
 could diminish his estate to their prejudice, he could not do so 
 fraudulently. 
 
 They claim, therefore, to be third parties as regards this con- 
 tract, but it is precisely on that account that they attack the 
 contract. And if they succeed in their challenge the result is 
 that the contract does not affect them at all. Neither the oblique 
 action, therefore, nor the Paulian action is a true exception to the 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS. 93. 
 
 mile that contracts do not, affect third parties. (Laurent, 16, 
 n. 382; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 587; Demolombe, 25, n. 46.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code falls into the same error of arrangement, 
 so far as the indirect action is concerned, when it says: Agree- 
 ments cannot enure to the benefit of third persons, oilier than the 
 creditors of the contracting 'party., who can, in virtue of the general 
 right which they haoe oyer the property of their debtor, exercise, 
 in the name of such debtor, all such rights of action as aceriu 
 to him from contracts or from any other source of obligation y 
 savesfinly such rights of action as are purely per son ah (141/202. 
 
 But neither the Egyptian Code nor the Code of Quebec in any 
 way suggests that the Paulian action is looked upon as an excep- 
 tion to the rule that contracts do not affect third persons. They 
 have profited by the criticism to which the French article has- 
 been subjected. 
 
 All the codes are very scanty as regards the oblique action . 
 
 The Egyptian Code in the article just cited says that when the 
 creditors exercise a right belonging to their debtor they do so 
 in his name, a point not mentioned by the French Code nor by 
 the Code of Quebec. (C. C. Q. 10310 
 
 On the other hand, the Code of Quebec says that Creditors 
 may exercise the rights and actions of their debtor, when to their 
 prejudice he refuses or neglects to do so; with the exception of 
 those rights which are exclusively attached to the person. 
 (C. C. Q. 10310 
 
 Neither the French nor the Egyptian Code has anything corre- 
 sponding to the words stating that there must be a refusal or 
 neglect on the part of the debtor to take proceedings himself, but 
 these words correctly express the law of France and Egypt as well 
 as of Quebec. The reason why the action 'by the creditor is called 
 the oblique action or the indirect action is because the creditor 
 represents not himself but the debtor or the debtor's estate 
 (Planiol, 2, n. 2950 
 
 As we have said, all the codes are very meagre about it, and 
 leave many questions completely unanswered. Moreover, the 
 history of this right of creditors is somewhat obscure. It is, 
 therefore, not surprising that upon many points there has been 
 great difference of opinion. Even now there is far from being an 
 agreement upon all of them, but most of the important points are 
 pretty well settled in practice. It is generally admitted that the 
 foundation of the creditor's right is the principle that the pro- 
 

 94 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 perty of a debtor is the common pledge of his creditors. (C. C. E. 
 555/679; C. C. F. 2093; C. C. Q. 1981. 
 
 It is, therefore, not as third parties but as the ayants cause of 
 the debtor, that they are given the right of exercising rights and 
 actions in his name. The debtor's rights of action form a part 
 of his property, and are included under the general right of pledge 
 which his creditors enjoy by law. A debtor who is embarrassed 
 or insolvent may feel indifferent as to his estate, and may not care 
 to take the trouble to prosecute claims which, if successful, will 
 benefit his creditors rather than himself. 
 
 Accordingly, the creditors, or any one of them, may prosecute 
 such a claim if its success would increase the debtor's estate, and 
 if the debtor refuses or neglects to prosecute it himself. And, 
 in principle, the creditors may exercise in this way any right of 
 action which belongs to their debtor. The French Code saj\s tons 
 les droits et actions, and the Egyptian Code says All such actions 
 as accrue to him from contracts or from any other source of obli- 
 gation, but always subject to the exception that the action must 
 not be one oi-s^-^pm^ly. -personal" kind. C. C. F. 1166: 
 C. C. E. 141/202.) 
 
 The expression in the French Code and the Code of Quebec 
 droits et actions is a pleonasm; it means only rights of action, 
 and the Egyptian Code is more correct in speaking of "actions" 
 onlv. (Douai, 13 nov. 1852, D. 56. 2. 21; Planiol, 2, n. 232., 
 
 But it is important to remember that the right given to the 
 creditors is in the most general terms, and that the article ought 
 to be interpreted in a liberal sense, as authorising them to bring 
 any action unless it is strictly personal to the debtor. (Dijon, 
 17 fevr. 1897, D. 98. 2. 31.) 
 
 It is for them to decide if they will bring the action or not. 
 (Cass. 26 juin 1912, D. 1914. 1. 307.) What actions are re- 
 garded as strictly personal will .be explained later. If the 
 creditors' right is in virtue of their general pledge over all the 
 property of the debtor it will follow: 
 
 (1) That the creditors must sue in the debtor's name and not 
 in their own name, as indeed the Egyptian Code expressly states. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1. n. 637; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, Traite de 
 Procedure Civile, 3rd ed. 1, n. 373.) 
 
 (2) That the action being really the debtor's, any defence 
 which is good as against him will be good as against the creditors 
 who represent him and sue in his name; and 
 
 (3) That the effect cf the action if successful is to realise an 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTORS RIGHTS. 95 
 
 asset of the debtor's estate. What is recovered does not belong 
 to the individual creditors who bring the action. 
 
 The right given in this article is to be classed with the other 
 rights which creditors have of preserving the estate of their debtor, 
 such as intervention in suits to which he is a party, executing 
 seizures to preserve rights when this is permitted, or executing 
 arrestments of money due to their debtor in the hands of a third 
 party. (See C. C. P. E. 668/760, 674 764; Anbry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 196.) And it is because this last right of saisiej 
 arret or arrestment is so simple and convenienl when the claim 
 is for a sum of money, that the right given to the creditors in this 
 article is not more often exercised. (C. C. Pro. E. 410/471; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 283.) 
 
 But there are many actions which are not simple claims for 
 a liquid sum of money, and it is only in these last that arrestment 
 is competent. The debtor may, for instance, have a claim of 
 damages, or a claim to revindicate property, or to exercise a right 
 of redemption, or to challenge, the validity of a will under which 
 he is deprived of a succession which would otherwise come to him 
 by law. And these are merely a few examples out of many which 
 might be given. 
 
 The right of the creditors to exercise the actions belonging to 
 their debtor is a right which can be traced back to the Roman law, 
 though it has undergone very considerable modification. See. 
 for the history, article by M. Labbe in Revue Critique, 1856, 
 IX, p. 208, references in Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, Traite dc Pro- 
 cedure Civile, 3rd ed. 1, s. 373; Dig. 42. 5. 14. 
 
 In the Roman law and in the old French law the creditor who 
 wished to exercise an action belonging to his debtor, had to begin 
 by getting a judgment against the debtor himself. And it has 
 been maintained that this is the modern law also. It is argued 
 that the history of the right shows that the exercise by a creditor 
 of his debtor's action is a sort of execution upon his property. 
 M. Labbe says: "It is laying hands on one of his assets; it is 
 beginning the prosecution or compulsory execution. 
 
 It is an attack on the freedom which a chirographic creditor 
 is bound to leave to his debtor until he is in fault. It is a way 
 of realising a pledge no less than by seizure and sale." Conse- 
 quently, M. Labbe contends that the creditor must have an 
 executory title, either a notarial deed prepared at the creation of 
 the debt, or a judicial acknowledgment of a private writing, or a 
 judgment. (Op. cit. p. 218.) But this opinion is almost univer- 
 
«? i 
 
 96 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 sally rejected. (B.-L. et Barde, l,n. 632; D. N-.C. C. art. 1166, 
 n. 223; Cass. 8 juillet 1901, D. 1901. 1. 498.) 
 
 It is introducing a condition which is not found in the code. 
 The action is not a form of execution, and its immediate effect 
 is to increase the debtor's estate by realising one of his outstanding 
 
 debts. 
 
 Still less is it necessary that the creditor should first have 
 obtained a judgment subrogating him in the right of his debtor, 
 although this view formerly prevailed among the French writers. 
 (Labbe, op. cit. n. 21; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 634; Garsonnet et 
 Cezar-Bru, Traite de Procedure Civile, 3rd ed. 1, s. 373; Bourges, 
 7 nov. 1900, D. 1902. 2. 124; D. N. C. C. art. 1166, n. 236;. 
 Dijon, 17 fevr. 1897. D. 98. 2. 31. But see Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 199.) 
 
 Why should we impose upon the creditor the necessity of 
 bringing one action in order to get judicial authority to 
 bring another? 
 
 The code does not make any such requirement and we cannot 
 add it. It may be regarded as settled in the jurisprudence that • 
 no judicial subrogation is needed. The effect of the article is 
 that the creditor is by law subrogated in the debtor's rights. 
 
 Nor is it essential that the debtor shall have been mis en cause 
 though in practice this is almost always done, because if it is 
 omitted the judgment will not be opposable to the debtor. (B.-L. . 
 et Barde, 1, n. 635; Garsonnet, op. cit. n. 374; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1166, n. 248; C. A. Alex. 20 dec. 1899, B. L. J. XII, 47; 
 C. A. Alex. 25 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 179.) 
 
 Nor is it even essential to the action that the debtor should 
 have been mis en demeure. It is sufficient if the creditor proves 
 that owing to the fraud or negligence of his debtor, there is a risk 
 of his suffering prejudice. We cannot insert conditions which 
 the code does not make. 
 
 / But, notwithstanding this principle, it is an implied condition 
 of the exercise of the right that the creditor should have an 
 interest, for interest is the measure of actions, and the creditor 
 cannot show this necessary interest if the debtor is acting in his 
 own behalf. It is only when the debtor is refusing or neglecting 
 to exercise his own rights, that there is any justification for the 
 creditor's claim to act in the debtor's name. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 196; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 628.) Upon this point 
 the Code of Quebec is more explicit than the French or the 
 Egyptian Code, because it says that the creditors may exercise 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS. 97 
 
 the actions of their debtor ivhen to their prejudice he refuses or 
 neglects to do so. (C. C. Q. 1031.) But the law of France and 
 Egypt is the same. 
 
 A judgment of the Mixed Court of Appeal states the rule 
 thus: 
 
 L' article 202 C. C. M. ne fait dependre Vexercice de la faculte 
 accordee au creancier de faire valoir les droits et actions de son 
 debiteur ni de la preuve de Vin&olvabiUte du debiteur ni de toute 
 autre condition, mais le creancier ne pent exercer les actions de 
 son debiteur s'il ne justifie pas qu'il a un interet serieux et quit 
 courra.it le risque de voir sa creance compromise s'il ne faisait pas 
 usage de cette faculte. 
 
 (C. A. Alex. 9 mars 1895, B. L. J. VII. 171.) 
 
 The creditor has not the necessary interest when the result, if 
 the action were successful, would not be to increase the estate of 
 the debtor. (C. A. Alex. 10 juin 1903, B. L. J. XV. 343.) 
 When the debtor is prosecuting the claim himself, although not 
 very energetically — even mollement — it appears that his creditors 
 cannot act in his name. Their right is limited to intervening 
 in the action by their debtor in order to prevent collusion and 
 to protect their rights. (Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, 3rd ed. 1, s. 373, 
 note 1; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 628; Cass. 30 juillet 1900, D. 
 1901. 1. 317; D. N. C. C. art. 1166, n. 253.) 
 
 And if the creditor brings an action and the debtor thereupon 
 proceeds to sue on his own account, it appears that the action 
 raised by the creditor will fall to the ground as having no longer 
 any foundation. (Amiens, 6 aout 1901, D. 1903. 2. 21.) 
 
 It is, further, an implied condition that the right of the creditor 
 should be exigible. For it is a general rule that a creditor whose 
 right is not due, or is conditional, cannot take any actions except 
 such as are of a merely conservatory nature. (C. C. F. 1180.) 
 The action we are now discussing is, it is true, conservatory, but 
 it is also something more, because it is intended to bring about 
 an increase of the debtor's realised assets. 
 
 Its object is to realise an unrealised asset. As M. Labbe says, 
 it would be strange if a creditor who could not sue his debtor 
 because the debt was not yet exigible, or if a creditor whose right 
 depended on the fulfilment of a condition, should be entitled to 
 interfere with his debtor's freedom. (Rev. Crit. IX, p. 218; 
 B. r L. et Barde, 1, n. 629; D. N. C. C. art. 1166, n. 220.) As 
 the Mixed Court of Appeal expresses it, the creditor must have 
 
 w. — VOL. II. 7 
 
98 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ii-n titre certain et prealablement acquis contre son debiteur. 
 (C. A. Alex. 4 avril 1894, B. L. J. VI, 273.) 
 
 But it is in no way necessary that the creditor's own claim 
 should be anterior in date to the debt which he is seeking to enforce 
 by the indirect action. 
 
 A man who contracts debts thereby pledges his whole future 
 estate as well as that which he has at the date when the debt was 
 contracted. Otherwise, when a man became insolvent, there would 
 be inextricable confusion. 
 
 Eaeh of his creditors would have a preference over that portion 
 of his estate which belonged to him then, and had also belonged 
 to him at the date when the debt to this particular creditor was 
 contracted . 
 
 It is clear, therefore, that in the application of this right the 
 date of the creditor's claim is immaterial. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, 
 n. 630; Laurent, 16, n. 396; Cass. 4 juillet 1854, D. 54. 1. 
 403.) From what has been said it is evident that the only con- 
 ditions of the right of the creditors to bring actions are: — 
 
 (1) That their claims are exigible. 
 
 (2) That they have an interest in the result of the action. 
 
 (3) That this interest is imperilled by the inaction of the 
 debtor; and 
 
 (4) That the action is not strictly personal to the debtor. 
 
 Whatever is recovered by the action falls into the patrimony 
 
 of the debtor. 
 
 The exercise of the action in the debtor's name by a creditor 
 does not confer any privilege upon the creditor who has taken the 
 initiative. 
 
 The creditor who sues does so for the benefit of his co-creditors 
 as well as on his own behalf. The action being based upon the 
 principle that the debtor's property is the common pledge of his 
 creditors, whatever is gained by it must be likewise their common 
 pledge. The creditor who uses it is exercising a right which 
 belongs to his debtor, and the effect of the action if successful is 
 to bring back what is recovered into the debtor's estate. 
 
 (Laurent, 16, n. 407; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, Trait''; de Pro- 
 cedure Virile, 3rd ed. 1, s. 375; Demolombe, 25, n. 131; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 644: D. N. C. C. art. 1166, n. 286; C. A. Alex. 
 25 janv. 1917, ^B. L. J. XXIX, 179.) 
 
 But if one creditor sues alone, the other creditors must take 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS. 99 
 
 care of their own rights, either by intervening in the action or 
 otherwise, or else the successful plaintiff who recovers an asset of 
 his debtor's estate may get paid in full, while the other creditors- 
 have to bo content with a dividend. (Planiol, 2, n. 294. ) As 
 the Mixed Court of Appeal has expressed it: Toutefois, l& oon- 
 cours des autres creanciers n'a lieu qu'autant qu'ils montrent eux- 
 mew.es une certaine diligence et qu'ils se presentent en temps 
 utile, faute de quoi le poursuivant etcmt seul en cause, garde pow 
 lui la valeur obtenue a concurrence de ses droits, par application, 
 quant a ce, a I 'action oblique'des princip&s qui regissent la saisier 
 arret. (C A. Alex. 25 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 179. 
 
 Any defence which is good as against the debtor himself is 
 good as against the creditor. 
 
 It must be kept steadily in view that the action belongs to the A 
 debtor although his creditor is allowed to prosecute it. 
 
 The defendant must be in the same position as if the action 
 wore being brought by the debtor himself. 
 
 From this it follows that any defence which would be good 
 against the debtor must likewise be good against the creditor \vho 
 sues in the debtor's name. (Req. 22 juin 1909, D. 1909. 1. 527.) 
 
 And this is true not only of defences founded upon a causes 
 prior to the raising of the action, but also of such defences as have 
 arisen since the action was introduced. 
 
 This last point is not always admitted. It is clear, for instance, 
 that if the debtor had an interest in challenging a certain deed, and 
 his creditors bring an action to challenge it, it will be a complete 
 defence that before the raising of the action the debtor had ratified 
 the deed in question. (Cass. 8 mars 1854, D. 54. 1. 191.) 
 
 But is it equally true that if after the action is raised the 
 defendant has paid the debtor himself, or lias made a compromise 
 with him, this will put an end to the suit by the creditors? This is 
 less obvious, but it would appear to be the sound conclusion. 
 
 It is not, however, accepted by all authorities. 
 
 The argument which some of them use is that the action by 
 the creditors is analogous to an arrestment. The creditor who 
 is the plaintiff is in a similar position to a creditor executing a 
 seizure, and the effect of the action is to prevent the debtor dis- 
 posing of the debt in any way which would prejudice the plaintiff. 
 (Demolombe, 25, n. 120; Labbe, in Rev. Crit. IX, p. 221. See 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 201 .) 
 
 7 (2) 
 
100 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But this view is not supported by any satisfactory reason, and 
 it has been rejected by the Cow de Cussatvm.. 
 
 That Court lias held that the debtor can compromise the action 
 brought by his creditors unless the compromise is fraudulent. 
 (Cass. 23 juin 1903, D. 1903. 1. 454.) 
 
 The doctrine is now chiefly in the same sense. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 639; Laurent, 16, n. 402; D. N. C. C. art. 1166, n. 269.) 
 
 So long as there has been no actual seizure of the debtor's) 
 property he can never be deprived of the right of dealing with it 
 according to his own judgment. 
 
 But if the creditor is afraid of the debtor dealing with the 
 right, during the course of the action, it would appear that he may 
 demand that measures be taken for the conservation of his right, 
 and the court may make an order for that purpose. (Dijon, Id 
 
 fevr. 1902, D. 1902. 1. 283.) / I 
 
 ( rUkou" * ■(*■***»■ 
 
 Can the creditor sue for an amount greater than his own 
 claim against the debtor? 
 
 Seeing that he is exercising a right of the debtor, and seeking 
 to realise an asset which will be available for all the creditors, 
 there does not seem to be any reason why his action should be 
 incompetent, merely because, if he is successful, the amount re- 
 covered would more than satisfy his own claim. 
 
 But as the creditor's interest is limited to the amount of his 
 own claim, the defendant can put an end to the action by paying 
 that amount and the costs, for a creditor cannot refuse to take 
 payment of his debt. (Laurent, 16, n. 406; Planiol, 2, n. 292.) 
 
 
 What are the rights and actions which creditors can 
 exercise? 
 
 (1) They must be rights which, if exercised, would increase the 
 debtor's estate to their benefit, for, otherwise, his inaction cannot 
 have been to their prejudice. (See C. A. Alex. 10 juin 1903. 
 B. L. J. XV, 343.) 
 
 (2) They must not be rights which are purely personal, a- 
 the Egyptian codes express it, or exclusively attached to the 
 person, in the language of the French Code and the Code of 
 Quebec. (C. C. E. 141/202; C. C. F. 1166; C. C. Q. 1031.) 
 
 It is clear that, seeing that the whole object of the action is to 
 realise an asset belonging to the debtor, and thereby to increase h$s 
 estate in order that his creditors may benefit thereby, they will 
 have no right to sue if the result of the action would not be to 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS. 101 
 
 increase the debtor's estate. So they cannol sue to recover pro- 
 perty, which, if recovered, would be unseizable, for they would 
 have nothing to gain by the success of the aetion. (Grenoble, 30 
 dec. 1896, D. 97. 2. 238.) 
 
 Nor can they sue in the debtor's name for an alimentary allow- 
 ance to which he is entitled, or for a right of use or of habitation 
 of a house, rights which by the French law are incapable of being 
 assigned. (Laurent, 16, n. 418; Demolombe, 25, n. 74.) Nor 
 can they bring an action which belongs to their debtor as Nazir 
 of a Wakf. (C. A. Alex. 7 mai 1896, B. L. J. VIII, 270.; 
 
 Nor can they, as a general rule, bring an action of which the 
 object is to determine or modify status. For instance, the creditors 
 of a husband cannot bring an action of separation or divorce. 
 
 Nor can the creditors of a husband or of a wife bring an action 
 to annul the marriage on the ground of a relative nullity, such as 
 fraud, want of consent of parents, where that is required, or the 
 like. 
 
 It is true that in these cases the result of the action might affect 
 the pecuniary position of their debtor, but they are all actions 
 which have primarily a moral rather than a pecuniary foundation. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 593; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 207.) 
 
 |5ut when a marriage is absolutely null because the parties were 
 within the prohibited degrees, or because it was not contracted 
 in the forms prescribed by law, the action to declare the nullity 
 may be brought, according to the French Code, by all those who 
 have an interest, and this would include the creditors of one of the 
 parties. (C. C. F. 187, 191; C. C. Q. 155, 156.) 
 
 But, here, if the creditors bring such an action, they do so in 
 their own right as persons having an interest, and in their own 
 names, and not in the name of and as representing their debtor. 
 (Cass. 30 juill. 1900, D. 1901. 1. 317; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 207, note 31.) 
 
 And, on the ground that the interest is moral rather than pecu- 
 niary, if the debtor has made a gift which he is entitled to revoke 
 on account of the ingratitude of the donee, his creditors cannot 
 claim to exercise this right of revocation. A wife may prefer 
 to live with her husband in spite of his faults, or a donor may be 
 willing to overlook the ingratitude of a donee. In both cases 
 there is a moral as well as a pecuniary interest . 
 
 But the creditors, if they were allowed to sue, would consider 
 the question solely from the pecuniary point of view, and, there- 
 fore, the law considers such actions as purely personal to the 
 
102 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 debtor. Upon the same principle, that when the basis of the action 
 is primarily moral it cannot be brought by the creditors, il is 
 agreed that creditors cannot bring an action for damage wilfully 
 caused to the body or reputation of their debtor. (Sourdat, 5th ed. 
 1, n. 73, bis; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 625.) 
 
 The question whether creditors can sue for injury caused to 
 the body of their debtor by a quasi-delict belongs to the law of 
 responsibility. 
 
 Right of creditors of incapable person to bring action on the 
 ground of incapacity. 
 
 It is generally agreed by the writers that the creditors of an 
 incapable person are entitled to bring, in their debtor's name, an 
 action to annul a contract on the ground of his incapacity. 
 
 Tin' minor, the interdict, or, in France, the married woman, has 
 the right of challenge, but the other party to the contract has no 
 such right. The incapacity is relative. 
 
 Although the incapacity may be relative, this does not mean that 
 the right to plead it is strictly personal to the incapable person 
 in the sense under consideration. 
 
 Tt means only that the other party to the contract cannot take 
 the objection. 
 
 The right to take the objection belongs solely to the incapable 
 person, but it is a pecuniary right, and, therefore, his creditors 
 should be allowed to exercise it. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 616; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 211; Laurent, 16, n. 420; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1166, n. 138; Ball. Supp. vo. Obligations, n. 310.) 
 
 But in France the jurisprudence is divided. (In favour of 
 creditors having the right: Paris, 14 nov. 1887, D. 88. 2. 225; 
 Bastia, 30 aout 1854, D. Rep. vo. Obligations, n. 930, Ire espece. 
 Against this view, Req. 6 mars 1878, D. 78. 1. 316; Alger, 
 22 fevr. 1899, 1). 1901. 2. 33. See Cass. 18 oct. 1910, D. 
 1912. 1. 233.) 
 
 The argument which has in some cases prevailed with the courts 
 is that the incapable person ought to be allowed to judge whether 
 he will avail himself of the plea of incapacity. 
 
 If he thinks himself bound in honour and conscience by the 
 contract, are his creditors to be allowed to interfere with his 
 discretion ? 
 
 But although there is some force in this argument, the better 
 view appears to be that creditors ought to be allowed to found 
 upon such incapacities. The basis of the action is purely pecu- 
 
OF THE EXERCISE OF THE DEBTOR'S RIGHTS. 103 
 
 niaiv and not moral, and if the incapable person refuses to act, 
 this is presumably because, being insolvent or embarrassed, he 
 feels no interest in the result. 
 
 What might be gained would go to his creditors and not to 
 him, and he leaves them to sue for it if they think fit to do soi. 
 
 Right to exercise a choice. 
 
 When the debtor's right is to make a choice or to exercise a 
 faculty, can this be exercised by his creditors? Some writers 
 answer this (absolutely in the negative. (Laurent, 16, n. 424; 
 Hue, 7,n. 195.) 
 
 But others make a distinction which seems justifiable. ' When 
 no right has vested in the debtor, but a mere offer has been made 
 to him which he may or may not accept, theroTs no right which 
 his creditors can exercise. If, for example, an offer has been 
 made to him to sell or to give him something, this is a mere 
 pollicitation which may be withdrawn at any time. Nothing 
 has vested in the debtor. On the other hand, when a succession 
 has opened in favour of the debtor, there is a right, and the ques- 
 tion is if his creditors may exercise it. 
 
 The debtor has the right to renounce the right or to accept it, 
 and his right is founded upon a pecuniary interest. It would 
 seem, therefore, that the creditors should be allowed to exercise 
 the right, but in France the question is controversial. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 601; B.-L. et Wahl, Successions, 3rd ed. 2, n. 995: 
 Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 214.) 
 
 A similar controversy exists as to the acceptance or repudiation 
 of a legacy which has vested in the debtor. The grounds here for 
 disputing the creditor's right are perhaps stronger. When one 
 accepts a succession he takes what the law gives him and comes 
 under no obligation to any one, but when one accepts a legacy he 
 takes what the testator gives him. Some writers maintain that 
 the legatee may have had conscientious reasons for refusing the 
 legacy and that his conscience ought not to be forced. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 622.) And. others say the creditors cannot exer- 
 cise the right, simply because it is an option. (Laurent, 16, 
 n. 426.): 
 
 But the more general, and, in our opinion, the more reasonable 
 view is that the creditors may exercise the right in this ease also. 
 (Demolombe, 25, n. 59; Fund. Franc. Oblig. n. 2639.) 
 
 It is generally agreed that in the ease of a stipulation for the 
 
104 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 benefit of a third party the right of the third party to declare his 
 assent is strictly personal and cannot be exercised by his creditors. 
 He may have conscientious reasons against accepting the benefit. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 623; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 209, 
 note 39; Dupuich, Assurance sur la Vie, n. 224; Trib. Civ. de 
 Quimper, 2 ma i 1893, D. 95. 1. 156.) 
 
 Rights purely personal are exceptional. 
 
 The general principle is that the creditors may exercise the 
 rights of their debtor. To exclude them it is necessary to show 
 that the right is purely personal to the debtor. 
 
 The Egyptian Code, in speaking of actions purely personal, 
 means the same as the French Code does by the expression " exclu- 
 sively attached to the person." 
 
 In Egypt it was contended in one case that by " actions purely 
 personal" the code meant all personal and moveable actions. If 
 this contention had prevailed it would have limited the rights of 
 the creditors to a very narrow field, but the argument was rightly 
 rejected. (C. A. Alex. 25 fevr. 1891, B. L. J. Ill, 244.) 
 
 The classification of those actions which are exclusively attached 
 to the person is not at all easy, but most of the actions of this 
 description have been enumerated. 
 
 We see that the ground for excluding the creditors is either that 
 the action is not of a pecuniary kind, or that, although it may have 
 a pecuniary element, it involves a moral element also, and that the 
 debtor ought to be left free to decide acr-ording to his conscience. 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 105 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 THE PAULIAN ACTION. 
 
 The action generally called by French writers action Paulienne, 
 from its Roman name Actio Pauliana, is sometimes called the 
 direct action, or the action revocatmre. It is dealt with in the 
 French and in the Egyptian codes in a single article. 
 
 The French Code, speaking of creditors, says: lis peuvent aussi, 
 en leur nom personnel, attaquer les actes faits par lews debitews 
 en fmudc de lews droits. (C. C. F. 1167.) 
 
 And the Egyptian Code says: Creditors can always procure 
 the avoidance of acts effected in fraud of their rights, and of gifts 
 and abandonments of rights to their prejudice. (Art. 148/204.) 
 
 Neither the Egyptian nor the French Code says that the debtor 
 must be insolvent before the act, or be rendered insolvent by the 
 act itself, but this is implied. A solvent debtor can deal with 
 his estate as he chooses. His creditors are not prejudiced if he 
 throws half of it into the Nile, provided that the half which 
 remains is enough to pay his debts. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 650; 
 Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 4, p. 219; D. N. C. 0. art. 1167, n. 97.) 
 
 The Code of Quebec is much fuller, and its provisions may be 
 given because upon most points they state the rules which are 
 settled by the French jurisprudence. The only changes which 
 that code makes are in regard to the period of prescription, and as 
 to the effect of a payment by an insolvent debtor to a creditor 
 knowing his insolvency, both points which will be referred to 
 later. Creditors may in their own nmne impeach the acts of their 
 debtors in fraud of their rights, according to the rides provided 
 in this secticm. A contract cannot be avoided unless it is made 
 by the debtor with intent to defraud, and will have the effect of 
 injuring the creditor. A gratuitous contract is deemed to be 
 made with intent to defraud, if the debtor be insolvent at the time 
 of making it. An onerous contract made by an insolvent debtor 
 with a person who Tcnoivs him to be insolvent is deemed to be made 
 with intent to defraud,. . . . 
 
106 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 An onerous contract made with intent to defraud on the part 
 of the debtor, but in good faith on the part of the person with 
 whom he contracts is not voidable; saving the special provisions 
 applicable in cases of insolvency of traders. 
 
 No contract or pay mad can be avoided by reason of anything 
 contained in this section, at the suit of a subsequent creditor, 
 unless he is subrogated in the rights of an anterior creditor. 
 (C. C. Q. 1032—1039.) 
 
 History of the Paulian action. 
 
 The Paulian action was taken over from the Roman law, and the 
 reason the French Code says so little about it is that the rules 
 applying to it were settled by tradition. When the legislator says 
 creditors may attack acts in fraud of their rights he does not 
 explain what acts are to be so considered. 
 
 The old French writers found the explanation in the Roman 
 law, and the French Code intends to refer to the traditional rules. 
 As Planiol says, the Paulian action thus offers us a remarkable 
 example of the conservation of legal institutions, and, of all those 
 institutions which are in operation in our day, it is perhaps the 
 one which has been best preserved through the centuries. (2, 
 n. 298. Cf. B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 646; Colin et Capitant, 2, 
 p. 49. See an interesting study of the history of the Paulian 
 action by M. Jean Acher in Rev. Trim, de Droit Civ., 1906, 
 p. So. 
 
 The Code of Quebec states in explicit terms the rules which are 
 implied in the French and Egyptian codes by this reference to 
 tradition. 
 
 There is, however, one important difference at least between 
 the Roman action and the modern action, if we adopt the theory 
 commonly accepted in France. 
 
 In the Roman law the action was brought by the curator 
 bitimrum or syndic for the creditors as a body, and the property 
 recovered fell back into the general estate of the debtor. It Was 
 a collective action. In the modem law it is an individual action 
 brought by any one of the creditors, and the property recovered 
 does not, at least according to the prevailing view in France, 
 full hark into the general mass. (See for the Roman law, Dig. 42. 
 S. and -22. 1. 38; Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 428; Roby, Romm 
 Private Law, 2, 273.) 
 
 In the French and in the Egyptian law, unfortunately, the 
 creditors have no way of acting collectively except in the case of 
 
- -z). 
 
 THE PAULIAN ACTION. 107 
 
 a oomtnergant. When a eornmerqctnt has been declared bankrupt? 
 
 his creditors can bring a collective action to have gifts and pa} - 
 ments made by him declared void, subjeel to the conditions stated 
 in the Commercial Codes. (C. Com. F. 446; C. Com. E. 227, 
 228/235, 236.) 
 
 But in the case of a non-trader there can be no faillite, but only 
 a deconfiture. There is no trustee or syndic, and every creditor 
 preserves his individual freedom of action; the race is to the 
 swift. (See Thaller, Turite Elementaire de Droit Commercial, 
 n. 1709; B.-L. et Barde, ObUg. 1, n. 682.) 
 
 Conditions of Paulian action. 
 
 If the act of the debtor which is challenged was gratuitous, the 
 only facts which the creditor has to establish are: — 
 
 (1) That the debtor was insolvent at the time of the act, or 
 was rendered insolvent by the act itself, subject to what is said 
 later as to this point, and 
 
 (2) That the act has caused prejudice to the creditor. But as it 
 cannot have caused him prejudice if he had no rights at the time,, 
 the creditor must prove that he was a creditor before the date of 
 the alienation which he challenges. When the act challenged was 
 onerous, there is a further condition, viz.:—' 
 
 (3) That there was fraudulent collusion between the debtor and 
 the other party to the contract. 
 
 These points will require a little explanation. (1) The debtor 
 must have been insolvent. It is essentia l that the debtor was 
 insolvent at the time of making the contract or that the effect of 
 the contract itself was to render him insolvent. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 219; Cass. 25 juin 1895, D. 1895. 1 . 486; Ohambery, 
 lOjuill. 1911,1). 1914.2.74; C. A.Alex. 14 mai 1903, B. L. J. 
 XV, 297; C. A. Alex. 15 mai 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 328.) 
 If the insolvency resulted from something which happened after 
 the act challenged, the creditor's action is not well founded. 
 (Ohambery, 10 juill. 1911, D. 1914. 2. 74.) When the act chal- 
 lenged is merely the carrying into execution of an agreement made 
 at a time when the debtor was solvent, there is no fraud and no 
 prejudice. On the other hand, there are cases where a debtor 
 does a series of acts the effect of which taken together is to render 
 him insolvent. If the court is satisfied that all the deeds are part 
 of the same fraudulent scheme they may all be annulled, although 
 
108 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the first of them may not in itself have rendered the debtor insol- 
 vent. (See C. A. Alex. 29 mai 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 454.) 
 
 As rho Roman law expressed it, there must be both consilium 
 fraudis et eventus damni. But when the debtor was insolvent at 
 the time of the act, or was thereby rendered insolvent, the fraudl 
 is presumed in the ease of a gratuitous act, whether the other party 
 av;i> aware of the insolvency or not. And when the act is onerous, 
 fraud is likewise presumed when it is proved that the other party 
 knew of the insolvency if prejudice is caused. This distinction 
 between gratuitous and onerous acts is not expressed in the French 
 Code, though it is in the Code of Quebec and in the Egyptian 
 codes. 
 
 But the distinction was made by the Roman law, and has 
 always been followed by the jurisprudence in France. (Girard, 
 Manuel, 5th ed. p. 426.) 
 
 The French writers say that fraud on the part of the debtor 
 must always be proved, but it is sufficient evidence of fraud in the 
 case of gratuitous contracts that the debtor knowingly and volun- 
 tarily caused to his creditors the prejudice of which they complain. 
 The debtor who is insolvent, and knows himself to be so, has no 
 right to give away the assets which ought to go to his creditors, 
 and if he does so this is a fraud upon them. It is not at all 
 necessary to prove that the debtor acted with the motive of injuring 
 his creditors, it is enough that he knew that he was causing them 
 prejudice. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 657; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 223; D. N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 126.) Fraude au sens de 
 Taction Paulimne, tie signifie que ceci, prejudice came en con- 
 naissance de cause. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 438.) In 
 the language of the Mixed Court of Appeal in a case as to an 
 onerous alienation: 
 
 En matiere d'action Paidienne, la fraude ne suppose pas neces- 
 sairement des manoeuvres dohsims, mais consiste essentiellement, 
 ■pour ce qui concerne le debiteur, dans le fait que, le sachant et le 
 voulant, 11 consent un acte qui le rend vnsolvable et porte prejudice 
 a ses creanciers en leur enlevant lew gage, et, pour ce qui concerne 
 le tiers, dans le fait d'awir eu oonnaiswnce de la fraude du debi- 
 teur, et a" avoir neanmoins ooncouru a Vacte. (C. A. Alex. 15 
 mai 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 329.) 
 
 Some illustrations will be given later of what is required by 
 the courts -as amounting to "fraud'' when the act challenged 
 is an onerous act. 
 
 The Egyptian codes remove any possibility of doubt in the 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 109" 
 
 case of gratuitous alienations by- saying that the creditors may 
 procure the avoidance of gifts and abandonments of rights agreed 
 to by their debtor to their prejudice. The codes do not use the 
 word "fraud'' at all in regard to these gratuitous alienations. 
 (C. C. E. 143/204; C. A. Alex. 12 fevr. 1896, B. L. J. VIII, 
 116; 0. A. Alex. 20 janv. 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 122.) 
 
 So the constitution of a wakf by an insolvent debtor is a fraud 
 on his creditors, and may be attacked by them after they have 
 discussed his free estate. (0. A. Alex. 20 janv. 1916, B. L. J. 
 XXVIII, 118; C. A. Alex. 25 fevr. 1915,' B. L. J. XXVII, 
 182.) 
 
 By the law of Egypt and by the law of Quebec it is absolutely 
 clear that a g-ratuitous contract is in fraud of creditors by the 
 mere fact that the debtor was insolvent at its date, while in the 
 French law it is at least necessary to prove that the debtor was 
 aware of the insolvency. What amounts to insolvency is of course 
 a question of fact; the onus of proving it is on the creditor, and 
 unless the insolvency has been proved, the third party who has 
 profited by the alienation challenged may demand that the other 
 property of the debtor be first discussed. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 220.) 
 
 The act challenged must have caused prejudice. 
 
 What amounts to prejudice is a question of fact, but in order 
 to annul an act as in fraud of creditors, it is a primordial condition 
 that the creditors have suffered prejudice. (Req. 17 mars 1909, 
 D. 1909. 1. 341; C. A. Alex. 28 dec. 1904, B. L. J. XVII, 47.) 
 
 It is essential to the action that prejudice should be caused to* 
 the creditor by the very act which is challenged. (Req. 17 mars 
 1909, D. 1909. 1. 341.) An insolvent person may contract new 
 debts, and the fact that the new creditor knew him to be insolvent 
 is not conclusive proof of fraud. It is so only when the effect of 
 the contract is to cause prejudice to the old creditors. 
 
 An insolvent debtor must live, and if he buys necessaries and 
 pays a reasonable price for them, this does not cause prejudice to 
 his old creditors. But, even further, by the French and the 
 Egyptian law, a preferential payment, or the grant of a security 
 made by the debtor to one of his creditors, even though this 
 creditor knows of the insolvency, is not challengeable by the 
 Paulian action. In the case of traders such preferential payments, 
 if mado within the periode suspecte, are liable to attack under the 
 
HO THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Commercial Codes, but the same rule does not apply to non- 
 traders! (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 663; Aubry et Hau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 231; Cass. 7 juill. 1896, D. 96. 1. 519. Cf. C. Com. F. 446; • 
 C. Com. N. 227; C. Com. M. 235—238.) 
 
 As the Mixed Court of Appeal expresses it, un nm-corrwrwf- 
 gant en Stat d'insolvabilite pent donner ses biens en paiement a 
 Vun de ses creanciers par preference a taus les autres, a moins qu'il 
 riexiste un concert frauduleux entre debiteur et creancier dans 
 le but de causey un prejudice illicite aux autres creanciers ; la seule 
 connaissance de Vinsolvabilite du debiteur, dans Vimpossibilite 
 de satisfaire, apres la dation en paiement, les autres creanciers ne 
 suffit pas. (C. A. Alex. 17 avril 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 287.) 
 
 The onerous payment cannot be challenged unless there is actual 
 collusion in order to prejudice other creditors, as where, for 
 example, the debtor sells for a price far below the true value, or 
 to persons closely related to or connected with him. (See C. A. 
 Alex. 26 fevr. 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 158; C. A. Alex. 9 mars 
 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 164.) 
 
 Upon this matter the Code of Quebec has made an important 
 improvement by placing traders and non-traders upon the same 
 footing. 
 
 Under that code: Every payment by an insolvent debtor to a 
 creditor knowing his insolvency, is deemed to be made with intent 
 to defraud, and the creditor may be compelled to restore the 
 amount or thing received or the value thereof, for the benefit of 
 the creditors according to their respective rights. (C. C. Q. 
 1036. See Mignault, Droit Civil Canadien, 5, p. 299, and the 
 jurisprudence cited there.) 
 
 Property alienated must have formed part of debtor's estate. 
 
 It is clear that the creditors are not prejudiced when the property 
 never formed part of the estate of their debtor, so as to fall under 
 their gage fiommun. It is on this principle that in the case of 
 life-assurance for the benefit of a third party, it is held that the 
 creditors of the assured cannot challenge a disposition made by 
 the assured of the insurance-money to be realised on his death. 
 This sum never belonged to the debtor's estate if the beneficiary 
 had a droit propre, upon the theory explained in discussing the 
 Stipulation pour autrui, and, therefore, it never formed any part 
 of the common pledge of his creditors. (Cass. 8 fevr. 1888, D. 
 88. 1. 193. Supra, p. 61.) 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. Ill 
 
 And when the assured has reserved the power of altering the 
 name of the beneficiary, the substitution by him of one person in 
 place of another does not prejudice his creditors. 
 
 Even if he substitutes one of his creditors for a beneficiary 
 originally named in the policy, this causes no prejudice to the other 
 creditors, for the assurance-money did not form a part of their 
 debtor's patrimony. (Cass. 3 mai 1904, Journal cles Assurances, 
 1904, p. 305. Cf . Peachy v. Riverin, 1895, R. J . Q. 7 S. C. 51.) 
 
 Debtor's estate must be diminished. 
 
 There must be a diminution of the debtor's estate. According 
 to the Roman law the Paulian action was not admissible when 
 the debtor had merely neglected to augment his estate; he must 
 have actually diminished it. (Dig. 42. 8. 6. 2; Girard, Manuel, 
 5th eel. p. 425.) 
 
 So if the debtor repudiated a succession or refused a legacy, his 
 creditors could not challenge the act, for the heir, unless he was 
 what was called a hceres necessarius, did not become owner until 
 he accepted, and the right of the legatee was not considered to be 
 definitely acquired till the heir's entry upon the succession. 
 (Girard, I.e. and pp. 870, 926.) 
 
 The French law maintains the same principle that there is no 
 prejudice unless the estate of the debtor has suffered diminution, 
 but there has been an important change in the law of succession. 
 
 In the modern law the property vests from the date of the 
 deatli in the heir or legatee, subject to the right on his part to 
 renounce it. 
 
 There is, therefore, a diminution of his estate if he makes the 
 renunciation, and it is, accordingly, quite logical that his creditors 
 should be entitled in these cases to the Paulian action, though by 
 the Roman law they were not. But, under the modern law, as 
 well as under the Roman law, it is probably otherwise with the 
 refusal to accept a gift. If a gift is offered to a debtor it does 
 not belong to him unless he chooses to accept it, and there is no 
 diminution of his estate if he refuses to do so. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 656; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 55. See, however, Aubry 
 et Ran, 5th ed. 4, p. 222, and note 16.) 
 
 The Egj'ptian Code is upon the point of renunciations clearer 
 than the other codes, because it says the creditors can challenge 
 abandonments of rights, or, in the French version, renoneiations, 
 to their prejudice. 
 
112 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Only prior creditors have a right to the Paulian action. 
 
 In principle, the attack can be made only by a creditor whose 
 debt is anterior to the act challenged. For subsequent creditors 
 could not be prejudiced by an act done before they had any rights 
 at all. (C. A. Alex. 15 mai 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 328.) 
 
 The priority, of the debt to the act challenged may be proved 
 by any evidence. (See Bourges, 18 juill. 1892, D. 92. 2. 609.) 
 
 But the rule that a posterior creditor has no right to the action 
 must not be carried too far. It is sufficient if his debt existed en 
 principr, although it was not liquidated al the date of the act 
 challenged. (Laurent, 16, n. 461; Hue, 7, n. 219; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 1, n. 688; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 220, note 14.) 
 
 And the law goes a step further. When the object of the act 
 challenged is to defraud certain determinate future creditors, the 
 existence of whose claims is foreseen by the debtor, the act may- 
 be annulled. But it must appear that the fraud was specially 
 directed against these future creditors; it must, to use the language 
 of the Cow de Cassation, be done pour nuire a Vexercice d'un 
 droit dont V ouvertwe Unit dejd prevue. (Cass. 5 janv. 1891, 
 D. 91. 1. 331. Cf. Paris, 31 mars 1896. D. 96. 2. 280; Req. 
 30 mai 1905, D. 1905. 1. 408; Alger, 1 mars 1906, D. 1908., 
 5. 32.) 
 
 If, for instance, a man, foreseeing that a judgment will be 
 obtained against him, fraudulently sells his property in order to 
 prevent its seizure by the creditor who obtains the judgment, 
 this might be attacked by the creditor. 
 
 In a French case, a husband, whose wife had left him on account 
 of his cruelty, anticipating that she would bring an action of 
 separation, sold his property to his brother so as not to have any 
 property with which to satisfy the pecuniary condemnation in 
 his wife's favour which he foresaw*. The sale was annulled. 
 (Cass. 5 janv. 1891, D. 91. 1. 331. Cf. Paris, 31 mars 1896, 
 D. 96. 2. 280: Req. 30 mai 1905, D. 1905. 1. 408.) 
 
 Similarly, where a man who had been arrested on a criminal 
 charge, and foresaw the probability of a pecuniary condemnation 
 in favour of a certain creditor, .made a gift to his children of all 
 his property, the deed was set aside. (Nimes, 2 mai 1892, Pond. 
 Frrmg. Oblig. n. 2789.) 
 
 And in Egypt the same principle has been applied in a case 
 where a debtor constituted a wdkf in order to put his property 
 beyond the reach of certain definite future creditors— en vue de 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. U3 
 
 Vavenir, et pour nuire a Vexercice de droits dout Vouverture Hait 
 deja preme. (C. A. Alex. 25 mai 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 
 
 870.) - 
 
 Proof of fraud in onerous transactions. 
 
 When the Paulian action is directed against a gratuitous act 
 of the debtor, it is sufficient to prove the insolvency of the debtor 
 and the prejudice caused to the creditor by the act challenged. 
 But when the act challenged is an onerous act, it is not sufficient 
 for the plaintiff to show that it caused him prejudice, and that 
 the debtor was insolvent at its date, or was rendered insolvent by 
 the acte meme, but he must prove in addition that there was a 
 fraudulent conspiracy between the debtor and the other party to 
 the contract to cause him this prejudice. 
 
 According to the French and Egyptian codes, as we have already 
 seen, the mere fact that a creditor knows his debtor to be insolvent 
 does not make it fraudulent on the part of the creditor to take 
 payment of his debt, or to take a security which gives him an 
 advantage over the other creditors, unless, the debtor is a trader, 
 and the act was in the periode suspecte. 'By the more reasonable 
 rule of the Code of Quebec preferential payments by an. in- 
 solvent debtor, although a non-trader, are considered to be 
 fraudulent if the payee is aware of the insolvene^. But 
 under the other codes it is not so, and there must be proof of 
 the conce rt ira uduleux. So long as the creditor is merely pro- 
 tecting his own rights he is not doing anything fraudulent. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 663; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 231; 
 Cass. 7 juill. 1896, D. 96. 1. 519; Dijon, 19 dec. 1897, D. 
 1900. 2. 364; Req. 6 janv. 1913, D. 1914. 1. 40; C. A. Alex. 
 26 fevr. 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 158; C. A. Alex. 14 mai 1903, 
 B. L. J. XV, 297; C. A. Alex. 30 mai 1895, B. L. J. VII, 
 316. See Beni-Souef, 22 mai 1900, O. B. 2, p. 31.) 
 
 But there are many cases of alienation, in which the fact that ' 
 the other party knew of the debtor's insolvency is sufficient to 
 raise a presumption that there was a concert frauduleux . (C. A. 
 Alex. 15 mai 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 329; C. A. Alex. 27 nor. 
 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 60.) If, for instance, the debtor sells 
 his property to a man who knows him to be insolvent, the buyer 
 is bound to inquire if the object of the transaction is not to defeal 
 the creditors. And this will be even more clear when the sale 
 is by the debtor to his wife, or to some person closely connected 
 with him and privy t© his affairs. In this last case it may ver\ 
 
 w. — vol.. ii. 8 
 
114 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 well be thai the sale was inerelj simulated. See C. A. Alex. 
 11 Jcv. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 87; C. A. Alex. 18 mars 1915, 
 B. L. J. XXVII, 227; Dijon, 4 juill. 1904, D. 1906. 2. 164.; 
 
 But, even if this be not the case, such a buiyer, thoroughly 
 aware ol* the state of the debtor's affairs, could not say that he 
 was in good faith because he preferred not to inquire what the 
 insolvent debtor was intending to do with the price. (Aubry 
 et Rau,'5th ed. 4, p. 226; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 662: C. A. 
 Alex. 11 mars 1897, B. L. J. IX, 309; C. A. Alex. 15 mat 
 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 328. 
 
 What amounts to knowledge of insolvency is of course a ques- 
 tion of fact. It is difficult to prove by direct evidence a person's 
 state of mind, and fraud is never presumed. The mere knowledge 
 by the third party that the debtor is in failing circumstances, or 
 that there are suits pending against him, is not enough to put him 
 upon his inquiry. Many men do not pay their debts who are 
 perfectly solvent. Much depends on the relation between the 
 third party and the debtor and the extent of their business 
 intimacy. If the third party has been doing business with the 
 debtor for years and has an intimate knowledge of his affairs, and 
 knows that, he has failed to meet a number of bills of exchange, 
 this will probably be a sufficient proof of his knowledge of the 
 insolvency. It is always a question of circumstances. 
 
 Onerous grantees preferred to gratuitous grantees. 
 
 The distinction which the law makes between onerous acts and 
 gratuitous acts as regards the Paulian action is not made expressly 
 by the French or the Egyptian codes, though it is by the Code of 
 Quebec, but it is thoroughly established in the French law. It 
 is one of those traditional rules which the code intended to keep 
 in force. It is usually supported by the following equitable 
 considerations. Between two parties one of whom is endeavour- 
 ing to make a profit and the other merely to avoid a loss, it is 
 equitable to give the preference to the latter. Suppose that, for 
 instance, the debtor has made a gift of a part of his property, and 
 the creditors challenged the gift, the creditors ccriant de dcmvno 
 mtando, as the old lawyers said, that is, they are seeking to avoid 
 a loss, whereas the donees certant de lucro captondo, that is, they 
 are trying to make a clear gain. We must certainly give the pre- 
 ference to the creditors. 
 
 On the other hand, suppose the deed challenged is a sale; the 
 debtor has sold part of his property to take it out of 'the common 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 115 
 
 pledge of his creditors, and the conflict arises between the pur- 
 chaser and the creditor. Here both of them are on an equal 
 footing - , they are both .seeking to avoid a loss- certant de damno 
 vitondo . 
 
 The purchaser who paid the price in good faith has an equal 
 right with the creditor to the protection of the law. 
 
 If a preference is to be given to either party it must be upon 
 some other ground. And this other ground is found in tin fad 
 of possession. 
 
 In pari causa possessor potior haberi debet. B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 660: Beudant. Contrats et Obligations, n. 532; Aubry et 
 Ran. 5th ed. 4. p. 224. note 18: Halton, 1. p. -'343. 
 
 Is the contract onerous or gratuitous? 
 
 As mentioned elsewhere, it is sometimes a delicate question to 
 decide whether a contract is gratuitous or onerous. (Supra, 1, 
 p. 97; add Trib. Civ. de Langres, 15 mars 1900. D. 1900. 2. 422, 
 and the note. - ) 
 
 . I datum 'if payement is an onerous transaction unless the thing 
 given in payment is worth much more than the sum due for which 
 it is substituted. "(C. A. Alex. 15 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 
 433.) 
 
 In France there has been much discussion of certain cases, 
 particularly those of provisions made in marriage-contracts. If 
 an insolvent debtor gets married, and makes a provision by the 
 marriage-contract in favour of the wife, it can hardly be contended 
 that this is onerous in a question with his creditors. No doubt 
 marriage is in a sense an onerous contract, because the parties to 
 it incur new responsibilities. 
 
 But the law does not allow an insolvent debtor to withdraw his 
 estate from his creditors in order to face these responsibilities 
 which he can avoid by abstaining from the marriage. 
 
 And the good faith of the wife will not avail to make the 
 contract secure from attack. The law does not allow an insolvent 
 person to place his property out of the reach of his creditors, if he 
 has the good fortune to find a woman ignorant of his circumstances 
 who will marry him. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 230; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 679; D. N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 216. ) < 
 
 But if, instead of the gift being made by one of the future 
 consorts to the other, it is made hy the father of one of the future 
 consorts, or by a third party, is such a gift onerous or gratuitous? 
 
 8 (2 
 
116 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 It is maintained that when a father makes a provision for his 
 daughter in her marriage-contract, the son-in-law undertakes the 
 responsibilities of marriage on the faith of this provision. If he 
 is in good faith, and unaware of the insolvency of his father-in- 
 law, the provision is onerous quoad him, and the bad faith of the 
 daughter will not entitle the creditors to obtain revocation. The 
 French jurisprudence is in this sense. (Paris, 9 juill. 1895, S. 
 1898. 2. 17; Req. 16 nov. 1910, D. 1911. 1. 500, S. 1912. 1. 
 101, 2mc. arret. See Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 53; B.-L. et Barde r 
 1, n. 675.) 
 
 But this jurisprudence is criticised by most of the writers, and 
 it does not appear to be supported by any sufficient reasons. 
 
 A father who makes a provision for his daughter on her marriage 
 is not, under the French law, fulfilling a legal obligation, though 
 by the Roman law it was otherwise. And the equitable reasons 
 are so strong against allowing a father to make matrimonial pro- 
 visions for his children instead of paying his creditors, that there 
 appears to be a reaction in France in some of the Courts of Appeal 
 against the jurisprudence of the Court of Cassation, and the 
 authors are almost unanimous against the theory that such, gifts are 
 onerous. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 229; B.-L., Le Courtois 
 et Surville, Du Contrat de manage, 1, n. 244; Godefroy, E., 
 De VExercice de V action Paulienne a VEgard des Donations faites 
 par Contrat de Manage, Revue Critique, 1887, p. 731; Orleans, 
 8 juin 1898, D. 98. 2. 284; and, for a full list of authorities, see 
 the note by M/Sarrut to Cass. 18 doc. 1895, D. 98. 1. 193.) 
 
 Effect of Paulian action as to sub-purchasers. 
 
 If a third party has acquired a right of property or some lesser 
 right over property from the creditor will the annulling of the 
 contract as fraudulent affect the third party? A has sold a house 
 to B; B grants a hypothec over the house to C; the creditor 
 succeeds in getting the sale by A to B annulled. Does this affect 
 C's hypothec? It is clear that the judgment cannot affect C unless 
 he has been made a party to the action. 
 
 It will be res inter alios acta. But if C has been mis en cause 
 will the judgment of nullity affect C as well as B? 
 
 In the first place it must be admitted that the registration by C 
 of his right will not affect the question. If C's title was bad the 
 registration cannot make it good. Registration by the Egyptian 
 law is merely a means of giving publicity to deeds; it does not 
 cure any vices of title. 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 117 
 
 La transcription pur elle-meme n' a joule Hen a la vaiidite du 
 droit auquel elle s 'applique: elle sert seulement a eonsolider el 
 a rendre publics dcs droits, a la condition que. ces droits existent 
 et aient ete valablement acquis. (C. A. Alex. 21 fevr. 1901, 
 B. L. J. XIII, 171. See Halt on, 2, p. 340.) 
 
 It is further true, that by the Egyptian Mixed Civil Code, the 
 fact that a contract which transfers property is void does not 
 affect the rights of registered mortgage creditors when they have 
 acted in good faith. (C. C. M. 197.) There is no similar pro- 
 vision in the Native Code. (See De Hults, Rep. vo. Action en 
 Nullite, nos. 30 seq.) 
 
 But this article, as interpreted by the Mixed Court of Appeal, 
 refers only to the cases of relative nullity which are dealt with in 
 the articles which precede it. If the title of the owner who 
 ■created the hypothec is challenged on the ground that he acquired 
 the property from a person who was incapable of transferring it, 
 or transferred it under a mistake, or in consequence of duress or 
 fraud, the annulling of his title is not to affect the rights of 
 hypothecary creditors. The contract by which he acquired his 
 title was voidable, not void ah initio. So long as his title was 
 unchallenged he was the true owner and could grant valid rights 
 over the property. (C. A. Alex. 6 nov. 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 3.) 
 
 In France, even in this case, the nullity affects the third party, 
 upon the general principle that the author could not transmit any 
 better right than he had himself, and that if his right was subject 
 to rescission his successor must be in the same position. (B.-L. • 
 et Barde, 1, n. 126; Bufnoir, Propriete et Contrat, p. 618.) 
 
 But, in this respect, the Egyptian Mixed Code has undoubtedly 
 amended the French law. 
 
 The question, however, still remains whether the Paulian action 
 is an action of nullity similar to the action to set aside a contract 
 •on the ground of a vice of consent, or if it stands in a different 
 position. 
 
 According to earlier judgments of the Mixed Court .of Appeal, 
 the rule stated in C. C. M. 197 does not apply here. 
 
 If the Paulian action is successful, and a judgment of nullity 
 is pronounced, this affects third parties, even though they may 
 have acted in good faith. 
 
 L'annidativn de la vente d'un hnmvuble prononcee pour fraude 
 aux droits des creanciers du vendeur, emporte nultite de la revente 
 qui a pu etre faite par Vacquereur ainsi depourvu de litre* ralables, 
 meme en javeur de tiers de bonne foi. 
 
] 18 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ,('. A. Alex. L3 mai 1908, B. L. J. XV, 292; C. A. Alex. 
 6 iiov. 1901. B. L. .J. XIV, 3. In the same sense, Haute Cour 
 des Pays Bus (Hollande), 28 mars 1884, S. 85. 4. 9; Laurent, 
 1G, a. 465. ) 
 
 Bui a Later decision of the Mixed Court of Appeal is in the 
 opposite sense: Attendu qu'il est generalement admis, tant en 
 doctrine qu'en jurisprudence, que V 'action paulienne ue saurait 
 atteindre un sous-acquereur a litre onereux, a moins qu'il n'ait 
 participe a la fraude. (C. A. Alex. 22 janv.. 1914, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 170.) 
 
 In the Native Courts there is a judgment of the tribunal of 
 Beni-Souef in the same sense. (Trib.-App. Beni-Souef, 31 dee. 
 1899, 0. B. 1, p. 331.) 
 
 These decisions are in aecordanoe with the traditional theory 
 of the French law, which is accepted as sound in France by a 
 majority of the writers and by the jurisprudence. According 
 to this theory, the question whether third parties are affected 
 by the judgment in the Paulian action must be answered by 
 making the following distinctions: — 
 
 (1) If the third party was in bad faith the judgment will affect 
 him. 
 
 (2 If he was in good faith and acquired gratuitously, the judg- 
 ment will likewise affect him, in the sense that he must return the 
 property, or, at least, the amount by which lie is enriched. But 
 ho may keep the fruits which he has percepted as a possessor in 
 good faith. 
 
 (3) If the third party acquired onerously and in good faith, the 
 judgment will not affect him. 
 
 In other words, the rule may be stated thus: the Paulian action 
 will be admissible against the sub-purchaser in those cases only 
 in which it would have been admissible against him if ho had been 
 the original purchaser. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 667; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 226; 1). N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 164 seq. 
 
 It is true that this appears to be creating an exception to the 
 rule thai a man cannot transfer to another any greater right than 
 he has himself— resoluto jure- dmtis resolmtw jus accipientis, and 
 nemo plus juris transferre potest quam ipse haberet. But the 
 answer is that the Paulian action is not an action of nullity in the 
 full sense of the term. 
 
 The judgment does not invalidate the contract in its essence; 
 it leaves ii still subsisting as between the parties, and revokes it 
 merely in so far as it is in fraud of the rights of the creditor. 
 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 119 
 
 it is, as we shall see presently, a disputed question if the judgment 
 revokes the contract as regards all the creditors, or if its effect is 
 limited to those creditors who bring the action. 
 
 But, without anticipating this question, it may, at least, be 
 said that the Paulian act ion is not an action to annul the contract 
 altogether. 
 
 The strongest arguments in favour of these views are: 
 
 (1) That it is the solution given by the Roman law, and thai 
 the intention of the codes is to accept the traditional theory, as is 
 shown by their disposing of the matter in a single article. (Dig. 
 42. 8. 9; Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 426.) 
 
 (2) Following the principle of the Roman law, the courts, us 
 we have seen, have always made the distinction for the purpose of 
 the Paulian action between onerous and gratuitous purchasers. . 
 and have consistently held that an onerous purchaser was not to 
 be deprived of the property unless he had been guilty of fraud. 
 
 On the other hand, as regards the gratuitous purchaser, no proof 
 of fraud is necessary. There is nothing in the texts of the French 
 or Egyptian codes to create this distinction, but the courts have 
 made it in deference to the traditional view which they believed 
 the codes intended to maintain, and also from considerations of 
 equity. 
 
 It is the general policy of the law to protect onerous purchaser^ 
 in good faith. But these arguments apply with no less force- to a 
 sub-purchaser than they do to a purchaser. If the sub-purchaser 
 acquired gratuitously, the creditors ought to be preferred to him. 
 for, otherwise, he would be enriched at their expense; he is trying 
 to make a gain — cert at cle lucro captando. But if the sub-pur- 
 chaser acquired onerously, why should he not have the advantage 
 of the rule in pari causa possessor potior haberi debet, that is. that 
 between two persons whose rights are otherwise equal, he is to be 
 preferred who is in possession. 
 
 And, in the case of immoveables, if we are entitled to look at 
 equitable considerations, there is much to be said in favour of the 
 sub-purchaser. A party dealing for value and in good faith ought 
 to be entitled to rely upon the register. If his vendor or mort- 
 gagor- appears on the register as owner, and there is nothing on 
 the face of his title to show that his ownership is conditional, the 
 other party ought to be able to deal with him safely, and then. 
 as soon as the sale or hypothec is registered, the purchaser s or 
 mortgagee's title will be secure. 
 
 In Quebec the Court of Appeal lias gone so far as to hold that 
 
 faJUk 
 
120 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 if an owner of property grants a hypothec in favour of a creditor 
 in good faith, even after an (action has been raised to revoke the 
 grantor's title on the ground of fraud, the hypothecary creditor 
 is protected. 
 
 La revocation d'une uente faite en fraude des creaneiers du 
 vendeur ne prejudicie pas a Vhypotheque consentie par Vacheteur, 
 mime pendant Vinstance en revocation, en faveur d'un tiers de 
 bonne foi qui lui a avwwe des fonds, le jugemwit sur Vaction 
 pauUenne n'ayant pas Vautorite de chose jugee a Vegard de ce 
 cre.ancier . 
 
 (Barsalou v. Royal Institution, 1896, R. J. Q. 5 Q. B. 33. 
 But. see, in Egypt, C. A. Alex. 22 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 
 170.) 
 
 And in France the theory that the Paulian action affects only 
 the author or accomplice in the fraud when the act challenged is 
 an onerous one, and does not affect sub-purchasers who have ac- 
 quired by onerous title in good faith, is thoroughly established. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1. n. 667; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 227; 
 D. N C. C. art. 1167, nos. 164 seq. ; Paris, 9 aout 1898, D. 99. 
 2. 485.) 
 
 Effect of the Paulian action as among the creditors. 
 
 Does the annulling of the act challenged result to the advan- 
 tage of all the creditors, or of those only who bring the Paulian 
 action? This is still a controversial question. 
 
 According to one view, the effect of the action, if it is success- 
 ful, is to bring back into the estate of the debtor the property 
 which, according to the judgment, he had no right to alienate. 
 This property, being restored, now forms the common pledge of all 
 the creditors, whether their claims are prior to or posterior to the 
 alienation which is annulled. The action is revocatory, and the 
 creditor who brings the action has not on that account a preference. 
 
 This was the Roman law and the old French law, and, in a 
 matter governed so largely by traditional rules, this is a strong 
 argument in its favour. (Dig. 42. 8. 1. 1; Girard, Manuel, 5th 
 id. p. 428; Domat, Lois Civiles, liv. 2, Tit. 10, s. 1, para. 1, 4, 7; 
 Voet, Comm. Ad. Pand. 42, 8, 11.) 
 
 The tendency of the jurisprudence in Quebec is in this sense. 
 {Chevalier v. Mart el, 1905, R. J. Q. 27 S. C. 356.) 
 
 The question is somewhat clearer in Quebec owing to the pro- 
 vision of the code in regard to preferential payments by an in- 
 solvent debtor. 
 
THE PAULIAN ACTION. 121 
 
 The Civil Code of Quebec says dial the creditor who received 
 such a payment knowing 1 of the insolvency may be compelled to 
 restore it for the benefit of the creditor* according to their 
 respective rights. (C. C. Q. 1036.) 
 
 These words would certainly cover all the creditors who had 
 rights at the time of the alienation, though, perhaps, they would 
 not cover subsequent creditors. 
 
 And it is maintained with some plausibility that the rule stated 
 in this article is an illustration of the broader rule that whatever 
 is recovered by the Paulian action goes to all the creditors. (C. 
 C. Q. 1036. See Mignault, Droit Civil Cantadien, 5, p. 296.) 
 
 On the other hand, the opinion which is now supported by almost 
 all the French authorities, is that the judgment in the Paulian 
 action is merely for the benefit of the creditors who are plaintiffs 
 in it. The other creditors cannot profit by the action to which 
 they wore not parties, and cannot, therefore, seize property which, 
 as a result of the action, is brought back into the debtor's estate, or 
 share with creditors who brought the action in the proceeds of the 
 sale of such property. 
 
 In fact, as regards them, the alienation made by the debtor is 
 still valid, and the property alienated has passed out of his patri- 
 mony. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 715; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 59; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 235; Bordeaux, 2 juill. 1890, D. 
 92. 2. 440, and authorities in D. N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 367.) 
 
 The French jurisprudence, though more hesitating, is mostly 
 in the same sense. (See Cass. 30 juin 1903, D. 1904. 1. 623, 
 and the note; Bourges, 18 juill. 1892, D. 92. 2. 609; Lyon, 22 
 fevr. 1893, D. 94.2.490.) 
 
 In a recent case the Mixed Court of Appeal has adopted this 
 view : — 
 
 La nullite qui resulte de faction paulienne n'est pas una 
 nullite absolue : 
 
 L'acte franduleux n'est annule que dans Vinteret du creancier 
 fraude et reste debout avec toutes ses consequences a, regard de 
 toutes autres personnes. (C. A. Alex. 20 janv. 1916, B. L. J. 
 XXVIII, 122.) 
 
 This conclusion is supported by the French authorities mainly 
 upon two arguments: — 
 
 (1) The French Code, in the single article which refers to the 
 Paulian action, does not speak of it as an action of nullity, or use 
 the word " annul," but says creditors may attaquer Us actes faits 
 par lew debit eur. (C. C. F. 1167.) 
 
 / 
 
 . 
 
122 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But, whatever weight may be given to this argument on the 
 interpretation of the French Code, and it does not appear to be 
 very great, it has no application under the Egyptian Code or the 
 Cod. 1 of Quebec. 
 
 The Code of Quebec speaks of "avoiding" the contract 
 (C. C. (,). 1033), and the Egyptian Code says the creditors can 
 faire annider Irs aetes. (C. C. E. 14:3/204.) 
 
 '2) A much more substantial argument is that to allow all 
 lli.' creditors to benefit by a judgment pronounced at the instance 
 of one of them is contrary to the elementary principles of law in 
 ivgiird lo the effects of judgments. 
 
 As to the creditors who did not sue, the judgment is res inter 
 alios acta. As the codes lay down very clearly, the authority of 
 the chose jugee is strictly limited to the parties. (C. C. F. 1351; 
 C. C. Q. 1241; C. C. E. 232/297; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 60; 
 I). X. C. C. art. 1351, n. 1172. 
 
 In answer to this, some writers say that tin.' judgment in the 
 Paulian action is not res inter alios acta as regards the creditors who 
 were not parties to it, because the creditors who brought the action 
 must, be considered as suing on behalf of the general body of 
 creditors. 
 
 The creditors who sue are mandataries or gerants d'affaires for 
 the others. (Colmet de Santerre, V. n. 82, bis, XIV.) . 
 
 But it is difficult to see how they can be mandataries without 
 any agreement between them and the other creditors, and their 
 position does not resemble that of gerants d'affaires, because they 
 are not interfering to protect the interests of others, but are con- 
 eemed solelj with the preservation of their own rights, and would 
 no doubt prefer to retain the spoil for themselves. In spite, how- 
 ever, of these considerations, and of the great volume of authority 
 in favour of the view that no person can profit by the Paulian 
 action except those who are parties to it, I venture to think that 
 it is not sound. The following arguments appear to me to he 
 decisive: — 
 
 (1) The Paulian action in the Roman law, ami in the old French 
 law, was regarded as an action of nullity in the sense that if the 
 alienation challenged was set aside, the property alienated returned 
 into the patrimony of the debtor, or, more correctly, was held 
 never to have passed out of it. 
 
 As Voei puis it, adeoque omnia perinde revocantur restauran- 
 twrque, ac si neque ali<'ii<iH<>, neque liberatio facta, aut quid aliud 
 gestum esset. (Comm. ad. Pand. 42. 8. 11.) . • 
 
 | 
 
 ■ 
 
THE PAUUAN ACTION. L23 
 
 This means thai there is a complete restoration of things to 
 the position as il was before the deed. 
 
 The creditor or creditors who bring the action may nol intend 
 to aci or behalf of the other creditors, bu1 they cannot help 
 
 doing- so. 
 
 The whole property of the debtor formed the common pledgx 
 for the creditors, and if a creditor succeeds in having an alienation 
 by the debtor set aside, the property of the debtor is thereby 
 increased, or, if we prefer to say so, it is shown that the diminution 
 due to the debtor's aci was only apparent. As Laurent Hays, 
 the creditors who sue represent the other creditors par la nature 
 memc de Vactian, for to demand the annulling of an act which 
 was in fraud' of all the creditors is a demand which interests thorn 
 all. And when the other creditors benefit by the action they do 
 so indirectly . 
 
 They do not invoke the rule of chose jugee, they simply find in 
 the debtor's estate a thing which forms part of the common pledgx 
 of themselves as of all other creditors. (16. n. 488. But I must 
 admit that even M. Siville, who edits the supplement to Laurent, 
 rejects his argument upon this point. Supp. v. 4, n. 674.) 
 
 Whatever conclusion we accept upon this point, it is clear that 
 the situation is different when the debtor has been made a bank- 
 rupt . A f aillite presents the indivisibility which mere decovftture 
 lacks, and the action by the syndic is a collective action for the 
 benefit of all the creditors. And even if the action is brought, 
 after the faillite, not by the syndic, but by individual creditors, 
 the benefit of the action goes to the masse. (Req. 29 juill. 1908, 
 D. 1910. 1. 409, note by M. Percerou, S. 1909. 1. 345, note 
 by M. Lyon-Caen.) 
 
 Prescription of Paulian action. 
 
 In the French law it is settled that the Paulian action prescribes 
 only by the long period of prescription, which in France is thirty 
 years, there heing no provision of the code fixing a shorter period 
 in this case. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 729; Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 237.) For the same reasons in Egypt the action will be 
 subject to the fifteen years' prescription. (C. C. E. 208/272.) 
 
 The Code of Quebec, with greater reason, provides that the 
 action' must be brought within one year from the time that the 
 creditor obtains knowledge of the fraud. Or, if the suit be by 
 assignees or representatives of the creditors collectively, it must 
 be brought within a year from the time of their appointment. 
 (C. C. Q 1040.) 
 
124 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 
 
 This action is known in the French Law as V action en declaration 
 de simulation. It is generally treated of by the French writers 
 as an appendix to the Paulian action. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 731; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 239; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 61.) 
 Like the Paulian action, it may be brought by the creditors of a 
 party to the deed, but, as we shall see later, the action to declare a 
 deed simulate is quite distinct from the Paulian action and is 
 governed by very different rules. It will be well to begin explain- 
 ing the expression a "simulate deed." I will adopt the definition 
 of M. Planiol: "There is simulation when the parties make an 
 ostensible agreement, the effects of which are modified or entirely 
 destroyed by another agreement contemporary with the first and 
 intended to remain secret." (2, n. 1186.) 
 
 The definition presupposes that there is identity of parties and 
 of objects between the ostensible deed and the secret deed. The 
 secret deed which modifies or contradicts the ostensible deed is 
 called a <mitre-lettre. 
 
 This is an old French term dating from the time when lettre 
 was equivalent to acte. Battler lettres was to give a written 
 acknowledgment. (In Scots law the term "back-letter" is em- 
 ployed in the same sense as Gontre-lettre.) As stated in a recent 
 French case, un acte ne peut avoir le caractere d'une contre-lettre 
 sans effet a regard, des tiers, qu' aidant quit a pour objet de dis- 
 simuler une convention vraie et d'y substituer ostensiblement,<pour 
 tons autre* que pour \es parties elles-vnemes, Une convention pure- 
 ment fiefh-e. (Douai, 15 few. 1876, D. 78. 1. 430.) 
 
 Different kinds of simulation. 
 
 The simulation may be made in three different ways: — 
 (1) The apparent transaction may be intended by the parties 
 as a mere pretence which is not to produce any effect at all, except 
 that of concealins: the true state of matters. For instance, an 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 125 
 
 insolvent debtor executes a sale in favour of a friend, it being 
 understood between the parties that the apparent sale is a fiction, 
 the object of which is to remove the property beyond the reach 
 of the seller's creditors. The simulation is here absolute, and 
 the simulate deed is called by French writers an arte firtif . 
 
 (2) The parties have intended to do something; their contract 
 is meant by them to receive effect, but it is not what they hold it 
 out to be. For example, A purports to sell property to B for a 
 certain price, but it is agreed that no price is to be paid, and the 
 contract is in reality donation, not sale. French writers call this 
 an arte dequise. (Bedarride, Traite du Dol, 3, nos. 1258 seq. 
 
 A common example of this kind of simulation is when a testator 
 attempts to evade the law of succession and to deprive his heirs 
 of the shares to which they are entitled by law, by making dis- 
 guised gifts to persons whom he wishes to favour. 
 
 In countries like England where a man is free to bequeath his 
 whole estate to strangers, or Quebec which has adopted the English 
 rule on this matter, there is no temptation to this kind of fraud 
 upon the law. (See, as te donations deguisees, B.-L. et Colin. 
 Donations, 1, n. 1236.) 
 
 (3) The parties enter into a genuine contract, and do not con- 
 ceal its nature, but they wish to keep secret the name of the real 
 creditor . 
 
 The simulation consists in representing A as the buyer or the 
 donee, or whatever it may be, whereas in truth A is acting merely 
 on behalf of B. A in this case is called by the French writers a 
 personne interposee, or a prete-nom. (See Req. 11 mars 1890. 
 D. 98. 1. 369.) 
 
 Rules as to actes deguises. 
 
 In regard to simulation which consists in dissembling the true 
 cause of the contract, the following rules may be noted: — 
 
 (1) The simulation itself is not a cause of nullity of the deed 
 when the parties have executed under a fictitious form what they 
 were entitled to execute under another form, and when, in spite of 
 the cause stated in the deed, there exists a real and lawful cause 
 for the obligation. For instance, an acknowledgment of debt 
 may say that it is for goods received, and it may be proved that no 
 goods were ever delivered. When a deed is proved to be simulate 
 in this sense that the cause stated therein is proved not to be the 
 true one, the person seeking to support the deod has the onus of 
 
126 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 showing- what the peal ami Lawful cause was. (Req. 9 nov. 1891, 
 I). 92. 1 . 151; Auhrv et Hau, 5th ed. 4, p. 057; C. A. Alex. 20 
 mai 1908, B. L. J. XX, -240; C. A. Alex. 13 mai 1903, B. L. J. 
 XV, 27!): C. A. Alex. 23 mars 1915, B. L. .1. XXVII, 237.) 
 
 This shifting of the burden of proof is quite logical. It is not 
 necessary that the debtor should state the cause of the obligation, 
 and if he does not state any cause it is presumed that a lawful 
 cause exists. 
 
 But when he lias made, or allowed to be made, a false statement 
 as to the cause, this presumption that there is a lawful cause 
 ks displaced. 
 
 Why should he state a cause which is not the true one unless the 
 true one is unlawful? Accordingly, there is now a presumption 
 that the cause which has been concealed is unlawful, and if the 
 creditor wishes to enforce the payment he must rebut this presump- 
 tion. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 391; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 557; Bufnoir, ProprieU et Contrat, p. 507; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1131, n. 153; Cass. 5 dec. 1900, D. 1901. 1. 192. 
 
 2 Although an authentic writing makes complete proof of the 
 facts stated therein until it has been set aside by the procedure of 
 improbation — inscription en. faux — it is competent to prove with- 
 out an improbation that the acts stated to have been done were 
 simulate and not genuine. 
 
 For such proof does not show that the official stated in the 
 document anything that did not take place in his presence. The 
 parties do not challenge the accuracy of what is stated in the 
 deed; what they seek to show is that their declarations made to 
 the notary were not sincere. 
 
 It is only when the good faith of the notary or public official is 
 called in question, that the expensive process of improbation is 
 necessary, and in Egypt,- improbation is not only expensive, but 
 involves the risk of penalty, for if the plaintiff fails to prove his 
 •case he is liable to a fine of 2,000 piastres. (C. C. Pro. 291/332.) 
 
 For instance, a document may state that A paid to B a sum of 
 money in presence of the notary. 
 
 It is not competent to prove without an improbation that no 
 money was handed by A to B, for this would be challenging the 
 accuracy of a statement made by the notary of a fact within 
 his personal knowledge. 
 
 But it may be proved that the money handed to B belonged to 
 him all the time, and that the payment was merely simulate. 
 (Aubry el Hau, 4th ed. 8, p. 351; Laurent, 19, n. 159, and 16, 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 127 
 
 n. 171: Pond. F'rcmg. Oblig. a. 7755; Dall. Supp. Oblig. n. 
 1'382; Paris, 15 nov. 1892, D. 93. 2. 291.) 
 
 -1 Winn the real intention of the parties is donation, bui tins 
 cloaJj that intention under the guise of an onerous contract, we h&ve 
 explained earlier that the- gift is not mill for want of authentic 
 form. (Supra, 1. p. 54. , 
 
 ,4 When the deed professes to he a sale and the buyer declares 
 therein that he has received the price, and gives ;) discharge thereof, 
 it is for the creditor who attacks the deed to prove that no price 
 was ever paid. (C. A. Alex. 12 mars 1914, B. L. J. XXVI. 
 282.) 
 
 We turn now from the discussion of the ease of simulation for 
 the purpose of dissembling the true cause of the contract, to con- 
 sider the general rules as to the effect of simulate deeds, hut, 
 before doing so, it is necessary to consider certain rules of evidence 
 which are well established. 
 
 Rules of evidence. 
 
 As regards the method of proof that a deed is simulate, there is 
 an important distinction between the case where one of the part iee 
 seeks to prove the simulation, and the case in which such proof is 
 offered by a third party. 
 
 (1) When the action is between the parties to the deed. 
 
 Seeing that, as between the parties, the secret agreement is the 
 true, agreement, the party seeking to prove it must do so by such 
 ■ evidence as is competent to establish a contract of that kind. 
 
 There was nothing to prevent the parties from having written 
 evidence of the simulation, and, therefore, when the value is above 
 P. T. 1,000, the party seeking to prove the simulation must do so 
 by written proof, or at least by a commencement of proof in 
 writing, supplemented by testimony. (Req. 5 juill. 1897. D. 
 97. 1. 468; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 351; B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 737; C..A. Alex. 9 nov. 1898, B. L. J. XI, 290; C. A. 
 Alex. 26 mars 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 301.) 
 
 Proof by witnesses is not admissible to contradict, or vary a 
 written contract . But this principle does not apply to cases where 
 the true cause of the contract was immoral or unlawful, or was, 
 as it is often expressed, a fraud on the law, and the simulation 
 consisted in giving a false cause, for here the party claiming could 
 
128 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 not procure proof in writing, seeing that it would have rendered 
 the contract nugatory from the first. If, for instance, a man 
 pays a gaming debt by a note in which he states that the money 
 due is for goods received, it is impossible for him to get at the 
 same time a written acknowledgment from the creditor that the 
 debt is, in spite of appearances, a gaming debt. (Aubry et Eau, 
 4th ied. 8, p. 351; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 737; Bedarride, Traite 
 du Dol, 3, n. 1294; Cass. 5 aout 1902, S. 1903. 1. 319; Dijon, 
 4 juill. 1904, D. 1906. 2. 164, and authorities in note.) 
 
 And it is the same when the consent of the party who attacks a 
 contract as being simulate was extorted from him by violence or 
 obtained by fraud. He may prove his want of genuine consent by 
 any method of proof. The rule was thus stated by the Mixed 
 Court: A party to a deed cannot prove by witnesses or presump- 
 tions that the deed was simulate a moins que son consentement 
 nc lui ait ete earache par violence on surpris par dol ou encore 
 que la simulation co)icertee nlait eu pour objet de couvrir line 
 Iraude a la loi. (C. A. Alex. 24 janv. 1894, B. L. J. VI, 242.) 
 
 The rules of evidence which apply as between the parties apply 
 to their ay ants-cause, except that we must not include for this 
 purpose a creditor among the ay ants-cause. (See C. A. Alex. 
 14 mai 1903, B. L. J. XV, 300.) 
 
 (2) When the action is by a third party. 
 
 It is universally agreed that when the action en simulation is 
 brought by a third party, and particularly by a creditor, seeing 
 that he could not procure written proof, he can prove the simula- 
 tion by witnesses, or by simple presumptions. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 1, n. 737; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 350; C. A. Alex. 5 fevr. 
 1891, B. L. J. Ill, 175; C. A. Alex. 20 dec. 1893, B. L. J. 
 VI, 72; C. A. Alex. 9 mars 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 191.) 
 
 But the presumptions must be weighty. (C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 
 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 108.) 
 
 Although fraud is not presumed, it is frequently easy to establish 
 it by proof of the circumstances. If the contract alleged to be 
 simulate was made between near relations, or between husband 
 and wife, this is a suspicious circumstance, and if a debtor who, 
 according to the ostensible deed, alienated part of his property, is 
 proved to have remained in possession of it after the date of the 
 deed, this is strong evidence that the transaction was not a genuine 
 one. And the fact that the grantees did not register the deed for 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 129 
 
 a long time may be a suspicious fact . (C. A. Alex. 29 mai 1917, 
 B. L. J. XXIX, 454. See the oases in D. N. G. 0. art. 1167, 
 nos. 389 seq.) 
 
 A vente a remere made when the debtor was insolvent, may 
 easily be found to have been simulate, and when a deed purports to 
 be onerous and it is proved that no price was paid or consideration 
 given, this will afford strong presumption of simulation. 
 
 But the relationship between the parties, the fact that the vendor 
 remained in possession of the property sold, or other suspicious 
 circumstances, are not in themselves conclusive. 
 
 (See 0. A. Alex. 11 dec. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 87; 0. A. 
 Alex. 9 mars 1905, B. L. J. XVU, 164; C. A. Alex. 11 nov. 
 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 21.) . 
 
 There is a. presumption against the genuineness of alienations 
 made when the debtor was insolvent or in embarrassed circum- 
 stances in favour of a wife or of a near relation, but this presump- 
 tion may be rebutted. (C. A. Alex. 26 mai 1914, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 300: C. A. Alex. 8 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 137.) 
 
 Simulation is a matter of fact, and it is for the court to decide 
 in each particular case whether the contract was or was not a 
 genuine one. (D. N. C. 0. art. 1167, n. 465; Dijon, 4 juill. 
 1904, 1). 1900. 2. 164; O. A. Alex. 28 janv. 1903, B. L. J. 
 XV, 110; C. A. Alex. 15 mai 1907, B. L. J. XIX, 254; C. A. 
 Alex. 9 nov. 1898. B. L. J. XI, 5; C. A. 28 mai 1003, O. B. 
 XV, n. 7.) 
 
 In judging whether the deed was simulate we must have regard 
 to the situation of the debtor at the date of the deed. 
 
 His situation may have changed afterwards. (C. A. Alex. 
 15 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 433.) 
 
 Effect of simulation as between the parties. 
 
 Provided always that the secret agreement or counter-letter does 
 not embody an unlawful agreement, it will as between the parties 
 to it have full force and effect. For it is the counter-letter or 
 secret, agreement which expresses the genuine agreement of the 
 parties, whereas the ostensible contract is a mere cloak, and, as 
 the law seeks to give effect to the real intention of the parties to a 
 contract, when that intention is not unlawful, it will allow them 
 to prove the secret agreement. The simulation is not in itself 
 a cause of nullity, but is so only in so far as it constitutes a fraud 
 
 w.— VOL. II. 9 
 
 
1.'30 THK LAW »)K OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 upon tin law or upon the rights of third parties. (C. A. Alex, 
 ler tVvi. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 95.) 
 
 Under the French Code this principle is stated expressly in an 
 article which declares, Counter-letters have effect between the 
 ■partiex to them only, the// do not make proof against third 
 person. (C. C. F. 1321; C. C. Q. 1212.) 
 
 fin in is no corresponding article in the Egyptian Code, but the 
 rule expressed in the first part of this article that counter-letters 
 have effect between the parties, is fully recognised by the juris- 
 prudence. For example, in a deed of sale the price is stated to be 
 L. E. 10.000, but there is a counter-letter by which the buyer 
 acknowledges that he owes L. E. 5,000 more. 
 
 Or. in a lease the rent is said to be L. E. 100, but there is a 
 counter-letter saying that in reality it is only L. E. 80. Or 
 there is an apparent deed of sale, but in a counter-letter it is 
 stated that the apparent buyer is not to pay the price named, 
 and is to reconvey the property to the seller at a certain date or on 
 demand. 
 
 In such cases, it is in the counter-letter that the real agreement 
 is to be found, and the parties seeking to enforce it may prove it, 
 subject to the rules of evidence which will be stated presently. 
 One of the parties to the simulate deed can bring an action to 
 prove the simulation, in order to prevent the other party from 
 taking a wrongful advantage of the ostensible contract contrary 
 to the secret agreement between them. 
 
 For one of the parties to the simulation cannot take advantage 
 of it to the prejudice of the other party. For instance, A sells to 
 B a certain property, and B by a counter-letter admits that the 
 sale is a mere pretence. B thereafter, in spite of the counter- 
 letter, proposes to sell the property, or to deal with it otherwise, in 
 a manner contrary to the intention of the parties as declared in the 
 counter-letter. A can sue to prove the simulation, that is, he 
 can prove the counter-letter, and he cannot be met by the plea 
 that in so doing he is founding upon his own fraud, for that plea 
 means that he had deceived the defendant, whereas here ex 
 hypothesi, B was a party to the fraud. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 1, 
 p. 176: B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 731; Bedarride, Traite du Dol, 3, 
 n. 1-286: Cass. 25 avril 1887, S. 87. 1. 149, D. 87. 1. -397; 
 C. A. 21 dec. 1909, O. B. XI, n. 33.) 
 
 A Quebec case is a good illustration of this rule. X, against 
 whom several actions were pending of the issue of which he was 
 apprehensive, made a cession of a part of his property to a friend. 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. U31 
 
 Ho afterwards sued for a retrocession of thejpropeii \ . alleging that 
 
 the deed was simulate, and that the defendant had agreed to rei urn 
 the property upon demand. The Court of Appeal sustained the 
 tiction and repelled the plea that X was founding on his own fraud. 
 {Dor ion v. Dorian, 1883, 3 Dor. Q. B. 376., 
 
 Similarly, if one of the parties seeks to enforce the ostensible 
 contract against the other, the defendant may plead that the 
 ostensible contract was merely simulate, and that the real contract 
 is to be found in the counter-letter. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 731; 
 Aix, 25 janv. 1871, D. 71. 1. 53; D. N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 415: 
 €. A. Alex. 9 nov. 1891, B. L. J. XI, 290.) 
 
 The effect of the simulation as regards third parties is con- 
 sidered in the following paragraph. 
 
 Effect of simulation as regards third parties. 
 
 By the French Code and the Code of Quebec it is declared that 
 •counter-letters have no effect against third persons. (C. C. F. 
 1321; C. C. Q. 1212. And see the lot dn 27 few. 1912, art. 7.) 
 
 There is no corresponding article in the Egyptian codes. But 
 without such an article the courts have power to declare that an 
 apparent alienation made by a debtor is fictitious, and that the 
 property purported to be alienated still forms a part of his 
 patrimony. 
 
 An action to obtain a judgment of this kind may be brought 
 by third parties who can qualifj an interest. (C. A. Alex. 27 
 mars 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 232: C. A. Alex. 19 mars 1903, 
 B. L. J. XV, 203.") It is agreed in France that by third parties 
 in this article we must understand two classes of persons to be 
 designated: (1) persons who have acquired real rights from the 
 parties subsequent to the simulate deed; and (2) the creditors of 
 the parties. 
 
 It has alread}' been explained that in some cases the expression 
 "third parties" would not include creditors; they are in many 
 cases regarded as ay ants-cause. 
 
 But here it is more particularly the creditors of the parties 
 whom the law desires to protect. By "third parties," in short, 
 is here meant all parties, who, not having figured in the counter- 
 letter, have an interest in invoking the dispositions of the osten- 
 sible and simulate deed in order to protect rights which they hold 
 from the contracting parties. (B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2406, ib. 1, 
 n. 740; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 267: D. N. C. C. art. 1321, 
 
 ( i*\A «* **^*~ tf ^ (2) 
 
132 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 1106. 91, 126; Limoges, 14 oct. 1910, D. 1911. 2. 393, and 
 
 dissertation by M. Magnol.) 
 
 The expression third parties here does not mean either the 
 pmitus extrmei, that is to say, persons who stand in no legal 
 relationship at all to the parties, nor does it mean on the other 
 hand the universal successors of the parties. 
 
 But that simple chirographic creditors are tiers in the sense of 
 
 C. C. F. 1321 is perfectly established in the French law. (Aubry 
 et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 268; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2409: Req. 
 15 avr. 1897, D. 97. 1. 247; Req. 15 juill. 1896. D. 97. 1. 460: 
 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1321, n. 126.; 
 
 Perhaps the clearest way of explaining the meaning of tiers 
 in this article is to say with M. Bufnoir les tiers, an sens de Vart. 
 1321, ser.ont les ayants-cause auxQuels la convention serait oppos- 
 able, si cette convention ne se produisait pas sous la forme d'une 
 contre-lettre. (Propriete et Contrat, p. 774.) 
 
 And he gives this illustration. The parties make an agree- 
 ment, and, as regards them, this agreement will be, not necessarily 
 what it is in appearance, but what the parties wished it to be in 
 reality. And, accordingly, they can invoke a counter-letter if 
 one exists, to prove their real intention. 
 
 But it is not the same with third parties, that is, with those 
 persons who had the right to count upon the ostensible agreement, 
 and would have been able to invoke it. 
 
 They must be protected against frauds of a nature to cause 
 them prejudice. 
 
 And so, as regards them, it is the appearance which must prevail 
 over the reality. The parties, in making an apparent deed 
 destined to be made public, are considered by that very fact to 
 have bound themselves to carry out the deed according to its terms, 
 in so far as is necessary to protect third parties who have relied 
 upon the deed. 
 
 Suppose, by way of illustration, that in order to facilitate the 
 sale of an immoveable, the vendor produces a lease from which 
 it appears that the immoveable is let for L. E. 1000. 
 
 There is a counter-letter by which the lessor acknowledges that 
 the rent is to be L. E. 800. If X purchases the immoveable 
 relying upon the ostensible lease, and claims the rent of L. E. 1000 
 from. the lessee, the lessee cannot defend himself by producing 
 the counter-letter showing that by the secret agreement the rent 
 was to be only L. E. 800. 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 133 
 
 The purchaser is a third party from the point of view of the 
 counter-letter, and it cannot be invoked against him. 
 
 Or, suppose, a man has signed a partnership deed as a partner, 
 out the other partners have given him a counter-letter stating 
 that he is not to be called upon to pay the amount of his share. 
 This will not be opposable to the creditors of the partnership. 
 (Civ. 11 mai 1853, D. 53. 1. 297.) 
 
 Or, again, suppose a deed of sale of an immoveable states that 
 the price has been paid, but a counter-letter declares it has not 
 been paid. The counter-letter is not opposable to a second pur- 
 chaser. (D. Rep. Oblig. n. 3204—2.) 
 
 It should be remarked that there are many cases in which third 
 parties are protected against the effect of the contre-lettre quite 
 apart from article 1321. The purchaser of moveables from an 
 apparent owner is protected by the rule en fait de meubles la 
 possession vaut titre, and the purchaser of an immoveable from 
 an apparent owner is protected if he reg^ersjhis_title before the 
 counter-letter which qualities or destroys his author's right has 
 been registered. This protection is given in France by the Loi 
 du 23 mars 1855, and in Quebec and Egypt by the codes them- 
 selves. (Planiol, 2. n. 1197; D. N. C. C. art. 1321, n. 109. 
 See note to D. 97. 1. 505; C. C. E. 615/742; C. C. Q. 2098.) 
 
 The counter -letter not registered cannot be set up against such 
 a purchaser. But there are other cases in which article 1321 is 
 very necessary to protect the tiers. 
 
 The protection given by the laws of registration against the 
 effects of oontre-lettres extends only to persons who have acquired 
 real rights and have registered them. 
 
 When the conflict is between two purchasers of the same. 
 immoveable, the second purchaser if he was in good faith and has 
 registered his title, will be preferred to the first purchaser whose 
 title is not registered. (Planiol, 1, n. 2619.) 
 
 But this rule has no application to the case we are about to 
 consider, in which the person who challenges the effect of the 
 counter-letter has no right which can be registered. The chiro- 
 graphic creditors of the owner of the property who has alienated 
 it. or has restricted his rights by a counter-letter, are in this 
 position. 
 
 They have no rights capable of registration, and if they are 
 entitled to challenge the counter -letter it must bo in virtue of the 
 principle consecrated in C. C. F. art. 1321, and not in virtue of 
 any rules of registration. (Aubry et Ban. 4th ed. 8. p. 268: 
 
j;;4 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2409. See Cass. 18 mai 1897, D. 97. 1. 
 505, and the note by M. de Loynes.) 
 
 Conflict between the ayants-cause of the apparent owner and 
 the creditors of the party who has granted a contre- 
 lettre. 
 
 Suppose X, the owner of the property, sells it by a fictitious and 
 simulate deed. The purchaser creates a hypothec over the pro- 
 perty in favour of a creditor who is in good faith, that is who 
 believes that the simulate deed in favour of his author was genuine. 
 
 The creditors of X bring an action to have it declared that the 
 sale by him was simulate and that the property in question never 
 passed out of his patrimony. 
 
 If they obtain a judgment to this effect does this destroy the 
 right of the hypothecary creditors? 
 
 This is in France a question which is still controversial, but 
 the better opinion appears to be that the hypothecary creditor is. 
 protected. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 740; Planiol, 2, n. 1199; 
 Aubrv et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p, 242; Orleans, 10 fevr. 1876, D. 77. 
 2. 113, S. 76. 2. 321, Pal. 1876, p. 1240. But see Colin ; et 
 Capitant, 2, p. 63; Limoges, 20 janv. 1905, D. 1905. 2. 127.) 
 
 The authorities who hold that the' right of the hypothecary 
 creditor is destroyed support this conclusion by the following 
 arguments : — 
 
 (1) The action en declaration de simulation differs from the 
 Paulian action in respect that its aim is not to bring back into 
 the patrimony of the debtor a property which has been alienated, 
 but to declare that the property never passed out of his patrimony. 
 The action must therefore be assimilated to an action of nullity or 
 resolution of the contract, of which the consequence is to declare- 
 the act annulled inexistent even in the past. 
 
 The judgment finds in short that the apparent deed never had 
 any reality from the beginning, and that no rights could be 
 conveyed by it. 
 
 (2) The purchaser, never having acquired any right himself, 
 could not convey any right to a hypothecary creditor upon the 
 general principle nemo plus juris transferre potest quam ipse 
 habuerit . 
 
 (3) The codes declare that those who have over an. immoveable 
 a right suspended by a condition or resoluble in certain cases, or 
 subject to rescission, can only grant hypothecs upon it which are 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 135 
 
 subject to the same conditions or to the same rescission . (C . C . F . 
 2125: C. C. Q. 2038.) 
 
 (4; Although the contre-lettre is not opposable to the hypo- 
 thecary creditor as conclusive proof of his author's want of title, 
 nevertheless, it does not prevent those who have an interest in 
 proving the simulation from proving it by any legal evidence, 
 and the contre-lettre will be a commencement of proof in writing. 
 (See Laurent, 16. n. 407; Dijon, 4 juill. 1904, D. 1906. 2. 
 164.) 
 
 But the sufficient answer to the three first arguments appears 
 to be that the intention of article 1321 of the French Code, which 
 declares that counter-letters do not make proof against third 
 persons, is to protect bond-fide purchasers who rely upon an osten- 
 sible title in favour of their author against this danger of simula- 
 tion. And to the fourth argument we may reply that, if the third 
 parties are to be protected against the simulation by the rule thai 
 the counter-letter cannot be set up against them, this clearly 
 implies that they must be protected against any other proof of 
 the simulation, and it would be strange indeed to hold that while 
 the law prohibits the use of the best evidence it permits evidence 
 of a weaker character. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 242; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 1, n. 740; Caen, 17 mai 1873, S. 74. 2. 46; note to 
 Dijon, 4 juill. 1904, ut supra. Cf. Limoges, 15 juill. 1899, sou* 
 Req. 12 juin 1901, D. 1902. 1. 55. 
 
 The policy of the law is to encourage the security of bond-fide 
 purchasers. Moreover, in a conflict between the creditors wh 
 wish to prove the simulation and the hypothecary creditor, the 
 latter has the advantage of possession. Accordingly, I accept 
 the view of those who hold that under the French Code, he is tt> 
 be preferred in the case under discussion. And this solution ma\ 
 be regarded as settled in the law of Quebec, where the language of 
 the code on this matter is practically identical with the French 
 Code. (Barsaloii v. Royal Institution, 1896. R. J. Q. 5 Q. B. 
 383; Desmarais v. Leveille, 1905, R. J. Q. 14 K. B. 382; Dorian 
 v. Dorion, 1883, 3 Dorion Q. B. 376.) 
 
 In Egypt the latest jurisprudence of the Mixed Court of Appeal 
 is in the same sense. La simulation d'un arte d 'acquisition n< 
 reflechit pas forcemeat contre le sous-acquereur de bonne foi qui 
 a traite avec Vacquereur fictif. (C. A. Alex. 20 juin 1918, 
 B. L. J. XXX, 482. Cf. C. A. Alex. 16 mars 1915, B. L. J. 
 XXVII, 219.) 
 
 That this result is desirable in the interests of security of deal- 
 
 1 1 
 
..,«A». 
 
 lJjtf THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ing in;i\ be admitted. But it is extremely doubtful if we are 
 entitled to reach it upon a fair interpretation of the Egyptian 
 codes. The latest decision of the Mixed Court does not distin- 
 guish between the Paulian action and the action en simulation. 
 The authorities cited in the judgment support the proposition 
 that the sub-pure ha sol- is protected against the effect of the Paulian 
 action. This has been discussed above. But the question here is 
 different. It is simply whether we can regard the judgment in an 
 action of simulation as anything else than a declaration that the. 
 property in question has always remained in the patrimony of the 
 debtor. 
 
 It is only by invoking C. C. F. 1321 that some French autho- 
 rities hold that the sub-purchaser can be protected. In the 
 Egyptian codes there is no article corresponding to article 1321 
 of the French Code, and it is a strong piece of construction to 
 import it. Without an express article the creditors may show that 
 a certain asset of their debtor was never alienated in spite of 
 appearances. But we cannot without an express text of the code 
 introduce an exception to the rule nemo pins juris transferre potest 
 quam itpse habuerit. 
 
 Whether the Paulian action is an action of nullity in the true 
 sense may be open to question, as we have seen. 
 
 But in the case of simulation there is hardly room for argument; 
 the judgment is essentially one which finds that the apparent deed 
 had no reality ab initio. As the grantee under it took nothing, 
 there was nothing which he could convey to another. Nor does 
 article 197 in the Mixed Code, protecting in certain cases regis- 
 tered mortgage-creditors, affect the question, because according 
 to the interpretation given to this article by the courts, it protects 
 only creditors whose author's title was voidable and not void. 
 C. A. Alex. 6 nov. 1901, B. L. J. XIV. ■!. 
 
 And it has recently been held by the Native Court of Appeal 
 that the judgment in an action to declare a deed simulate affects 
 sub-purchasers. 
 
 A fictitious contract of sale had been entered into between the 
 husband and wife with the object of prejudicing the husband's 
 creditors . 
 
 The contract was set aside at the instance of the creditors as 
 being simulate, and it was held that the nullity might be enforced 
 by the creditors against a hond-fide purchaser from the wife. 
 His only remedy was an action against her for damages. C. A. 
 28 mai 1913, O. B. XV, n. 7.)' 
 
 Jr A^C 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED .SIMULATE. 137 
 
 1 1 may be remarked in conclusion that even the French autho- 
 rities in favour of protecting sub-purchasers do not go the length 
 of protecting a purchaser by gratuitous title. The judgment 
 finding a deed simulate will always affect sous-acquereurs by 
 gratuitous title, because they could not be allowed to enrich them- 
 selves at the expense Of the creditors of their author. (Aubrv 
 et Ran, 5th ed. 4. p. 242. note 53. 
 
 Distinction between the action en simulation and the 
 Paulian action. 
 
 The action to declare a deed simulated has some analogies with 
 the Paulian action, and it is usually treated of by legal writers in 
 connection with that action. But. the rules which apply to the 
 two things are different, though, unfortunately, the two actions 
 have not always been clearly distinguished from one another. 
 
 This is not surprising, because the two actions are frequently 
 combined. The deed is challenged both as fraudulent and as 
 simulate, but the two things are distinct, and the grounds of 
 action arc alternative. (C. A. Alex. 3 nov. 1910, B. L. J. 
 XXIII, 3: C. A. Alex. 18 avr. 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 259; 
 C. A. Alex. 13 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 433; C. A. Alex. 
 6 fevr. 1917, B.' L. J. XXIX, 198.) 
 
 The rule has been thus laid down: quoique les conditions 
 de Vexercioe de Taction paulienneet de V action en simulation soient 
 differentes, les arguments on motifs a Vappui de Vune ou de V autre 
 out line grande analogie et sont quelquefois identiques, V inter esse 
 se trowvant le phis souvent dans Vimpossibilite de preciser et etant 
 par suite force de proposer les deux actions alternativement. 
 
 II serait done tres dane/ereux pour la bonne administration de 
 la jmtici de s'inspirer d'un formalisme rigoureux et de s'attadier 
 plufot a la lettre qu'a V esprit des conclusions des creanciers dans 
 la qualification de V action exercee par eux en vac de faire annuler 
 les actcs par lesquels des debiteurs pen scrupuleux se concertent 
 avec des tiers pour les frusirer dans Vexercice de lews droits. 
 (C. A. Alex. 22 juin 1915, Gaz. Trib. V. p. 168.) 
 
 Pr, as it is expressed in a later ease. Rien riempecheun, 
 creancier de transformer Faction paulienne en action de simula- 
 tion lorsque les elements de la cause etablissent la fictivite de 
 Facte attaquee, Get acte ne pouvant amir aucune force probante 
 par lui-meme. 0. A. Alex. 29 mai 1918. B. L. J. XXIX, 
 454.) 
 
 Where the deed is merelv fraudulent, there is a genuine aliena- 
 tion which is intended to remove the property out of the patrimony 
 
138 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 of the grantor in fraud of his creditors. But, where the deed is 
 simulate, there uever was any alienation at all, but merely the 
 pretence of one. 
 
 The object of the action is to fix the true amount of the debtor's 
 estate, and to show that curtain things belong- to it which the 
 debtor is trying to conceal by pretending that he has parted with 
 them in favour of another. 
 
 They have not been alienated; he has only made a pretence 
 of alienating them. (C. A. Alex. 22 janv. 1914, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 170.) 
 
 The Paulian action is an action solely for the benefit of creditors, 
 wherea s the action en simulation may be brought by one of the 
 parties to the simulate deed, or by any person having an interest. 
 (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 1, p. 176; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 731; 
 Cass. 25 avr. 1887, D. 87. 1. 397. 
 
 According to the Egyptian jurisprudence, the parties to the 
 deed must always be mis en cause. Pour juger de la simulation 
 (J 'mi aete, it faut que tons ceux qui y ont participe et qui ont 
 interet a soutenir sa validite soient mis en cause: si toutes les 
 parties ne sont pas assignees, la demande est ir re rex able. 
 
 (C. A. Alex. 3 mai 1899, B. L. J. XI, 203; C. A. Alex. 
 22 mars 1900, B. L. J. XII, 172. Contra, in Quebec, Desmarais 
 v. Leveille, 1906, R. J. Q. 14 K. B. 382.) 
 
 It is, however, in the case where the action en simulation is 
 brought by the creditors of the grantor, that there is a risk of 
 confusing it with the Paulian action. The following are the 
 main points of difference between the two actions: — 
 
 (1) The creditors do not need to prove that the simulation was , 
 in fraud of their rights, and still less that there was complicity 
 between the debtor and the third party. They need only to show 
 that they have an interest in proving the simulation. It is clear 
 that if the other property of the debtor is insufficient to pay their 
 claims they are entitled to prove that the property in question 
 forms a part of the debtor's assets irrespective of the motive which 
 has induced the debtor to conceal that fact. (Planiol, 2, n. 1203; 
 Cass. 31 juill. 1872, D. 73. 1. 340.; 
 
 But the creditors do not need to prove the insolvency of the 
 debtor; they simply ask the court to fix what is the estate over 
 which their common pledge exists. And the creditor has a right 
 to choose among the assets of his debtor those which he will seize 
 in execution. (Colin et Capitant. 2, p. 62: B.-L. et Barde, 1, 
 n. 733; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 240.) 
 
 2 In ordf^fo b^ng the. action en simulation it is not neoes- 
 
 ■ rJL.- 
 
THE ACTION TO DECLARE A DEED SIMULATE. 139 
 
 sary that the debts due to the creditors should be anterior to the 
 simulate alienation. 
 
 For, although the debts due to them may have been incurred bj 
 the debtor at a date later than the alienation, nevertheless, but foj 
 the alienation, or rather the pretended alienation, the property in 
 question would have been available for the creditors. (B.-L. et 
 Barde, 1, n. 733; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4. p. 240; Dijon. 4 
 juillet 1904, D. 1906. 2. 164; C. A. Alex. 8 mars 1899. B. L. J. 
 XI, 150; C. A. Alex. 12 mai 1898, B. L. J. X, 271. 
 
 (3) It is not necessary to prove that the debtor was insolvent 
 at the date of the deed, except in so far as proof of insolvency 
 may be held to establish its fictitious character. (Aubry et Rau. 
 5th ed. 4, p. 240; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 733; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1167, n. 446; C. A. Alex. 23 Janvier 1890, B. L. J. II, 
 106.) 
 
 __,. According to one view the action en simulation is imprescrip- 
 tible, because an act which is inexistent cannot become existent 
 by any lapse of time. (Colin et Capitant, 2. p. 63. 
 
 But the prevailing opinion is that this action is subject to the 
 ordinary long prescription which is in France 30 years, and in 
 Egypt 15 years. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 458; Limoges. 
 15 mars 1895, sous Civ. 12 janv. 1897. D. 97. 1. 273. 
 
 Distinction between action en simulation and the 
 indirect action. 
 
 Nor must the action en simulation be confounded with the 
 indirect action by creditors in the name of their debtor. Creditors 
 would no doubt be entitled to sue on behalf of their debtor for the 
 restitution of property belonging to him. But that action would 
 be less to their advantage than the action which we are consider- 
 ing. If they were suing on behalf of their debtor, they would 
 have to sue under the conditions which would apply to an action 
 by him. 
 
 (1) They would have to prove that the secret agreement was 
 the true contract between the parties, and this would mean in most 
 cases the necessity of having a commencement of proof in writing, 
 whereas, when they bring the action en simulation, on the other 
 hand, all methods of proof are open to them. 
 
 (2) They might be met by any defence which might be made 
 against the debtor himself. (B.-L. et Barde. 1. n. 734: supra, 
 p. 99.) 
 
 - 
 
140 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER VII. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 
 
 We have now concluded our examination of obligations arising 
 from an agreement, and we come to discuss those obligations' 
 which arise not from any agreement but from certain acts. An 
 act which creates an obligation may be: — 
 
 (1) Benefit-producing; or 
 
 (2) Causing damage. 
 
 The first head covers what are called in the French law quasi- 
 contracts, and the second what are called in the French law delicts 
 and quasi-delicts. 
 
 We shall first deal with the quasi-contracts, or those obligations 
 which result from benefit-producing acts. 
 
 The French Code explains the law as to two of these: — 
 
 (1) Negotiorum gestio, and 
 
 (2) Repetition of a \payment not due. 
 
 (C. C. F. 1371 seq.; C. C. Q. 1043 seq.) 
 
 But these are by no means the only benefit-producing acts, 
 and the Egyptian Code, in spite of its brevity, makes it clearer 
 than the French Code that an obligation arises when one party 
 has intentionally procured a benefit for another. The broad prin- 
 ciple underlying the whole matter is nut ne doit s'enrichir injuste- 
 ment au prejudice d'autrui. Both negotiorum gestio and le paie- 
 ment de Vindu are illustrations of this general rule, and there are 
 other applications of it which cannot be brought under either of 
 these, and which Planiol aptly designates as quasi-contrats in- 
 nommes. (2, nos. 813, 933. Cf. Cass. 18 oct. 1904, D. 1905. 
 1. 119; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2789.) 
 
 The Egyptian codes state the rule broadly. The single article 
 dealing with unjust enrichment says: the act of one person in- 
 tentionally procuring a benefit for another 'binds that other person 
 to account for any expenses and losses incurred bif the former up 
 
tt^M 
 
 
 OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 141 
 
 to an amount equal to the profit so obtained. (C. 0. E. 144/ 
 200.! 
 
 The article in the Egyptian codes probably intends to lay down 
 a general rule which will give a claim to any person who has acted 
 as a negotiorum gestor, though it does not use the expression 
 gestion d'affaires. 
 
 In the jurisprudence, however, this expression is frequently 
 used in cases in which this article has been interpreted, as where 
 the Mixed Court says, La gestion d'affaires consiste purement et 
 simplement a faire sans mandat V affaire d'autrui et a lui procurer 
 a son insu une utilite directe et von occasionmelle . (C. A. Alex. 
 9 fevr. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 118. Cf. C. A. Alex. 17 dee. 
 1902, B. L. J. XV, 64.) 
 
 But in other cases the Mixed Court has spoken of the action by 
 the gestor as the action de in rem verso, although in the French 
 law this name is given, as will be explained later, to an action 
 which is distinguished from the action arising from gestion 
 d'affaires. (C. A. Alex. 21 dec. 1892, B. L. J. V, 85.) 
 
 According to the French jurisprudence, the actio de in rem 
 verso lies in certain eases against a person who has been enriched, 
 although the party claiming reimbursement did not intend to 
 create the benefit. But the Egyptian Code by using the word 
 "intentionally" may be thought to have excluded the claim in 
 such cases. On the other hand, in the French law where there 
 has been a gestion d'affaires, the claim of the gerant is not limited 
 to reimbursement for the profit still subsisting at the date of the 
 action, whereas the Egyptian Code lias been interpreted as limit- 
 ing the claim to this amount. But this decision seems doubtful. 
 It will be referred to later. (C. A. Alex. 13 fevr. 1895, B. L. J. 
 VII, 122. Cf. Pand. Franc, vo. Affaires, Gestion d', n. 317; 
 D. Rep. Oblig. n. 5467. 
 
 If this decision is correct the Egyptian codes, in attempting 
 to state a broad rule, have somewhat narrowed the French law as 
 to gestion d'affaires, and it is not certain that they have left 
 room for any claim such as is allowed by the modern French law 
 in the oases where there has been an unintentional enrichment. 
 (See infra, pp. 163 seq.) 
 
 It is probable, however, that the courts will hold that such a 
 claim exists upon general principles of equity, and that the code 
 intends to recognise the broad principle above cited. 
 
 ;'■■' 
 
 
] 42 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Nul ne doit s'enrichir injustement au prejudice d'autrui. 
 
 This principle receives recognition in a number of articles in 
 the code. (SeeC. ( . E. gp/90; 1:31/191; 344/430. , 
 
 As regards the quasi-contract of gestion d'affaires, it is pro- 
 bably safe to assume that the Egyptian codes intend to retain 
 the rules established in the French law, except in so far as article 
 144/205 has made any change. I will, therefore, state the French 
 rules upon this subject, and explain also the actio de in rem verso 
 in the sense of the French writers, though as already stated there 
 is a doubt if, under the Egyptian legislation any such action is 
 available where the enrichment has been unintentionally procured. 
 But before doing so it will be well to explain shortly what is 
 meant in the French law by the term quasi-contract, although the 
 Egyptian Code, perhaps wisely, avoids the use of that term 
 altogether. - 
 
 Quasi-contracts. 
 
 The French Code does not give any enumeration of the sources 
 of obligations. But in the arrangement of that work obligations 
 are divided into two groups, viz.: (1) contracts or obligations 
 arising from the agreement of parties which are dealt with in 
 title three of book throe; and (2) obligations which arise without 
 agreement, or as they are styled, engagements, which are dealt 
 with in title 4 of the same book. 
 
 This is the scheme of Pothier. He devotes two sections to the 
 sources, or, as he calls them, the "causes" of obligations. The 
 first he heads " Of Contracts," and the second " Of the other causes 
 of obligations." 
 
 The sub-divisions of the second group are quasi-contracts, 
 ■delicts, quasi-delicts, and the operation of the law in certain cases. 
 (Oblig. n. 2.) 
 
 The Code of Quebec simply enumerates five sources of obliga- 
 tions, contracts, quasi-contracts, offences, quasi-offences and the 
 operation of the law solely. (C. C. Q. 983.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code, without giving any enumeration, divides 
 obligations into three kinds: — 
 
 (1) Contracts. 
 
 (2) Obligations created by an act or event. 
 
 3 Obligations created by law. (Title II. chapters II., 
 III.. IV. 
 But the twofold division of the French Code and of Pothier is 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 143 
 
 really more philosophical. The fundamental distinction is be- 
 tween obligations which arise from the agreement of parties and 
 those which arise without any such agreement. All non-con- 
 tractual obligations are obligations created by Law. In these the 
 liability was created without consent. It is a liability which the 
 party must bear merely because the law says he must bear it. In 
 a contract on the other hand, the party has surrendered voluntarily 
 a portion of his freedom. He is now bound to pay the debt, or if 
 the contract is of a kind of which the actual performance is not 
 enforced, he will be bound to pay damages, if he does not perform 
 his promise. 
 
 But when a man is found liable on account of a delict or of a 
 quasi-delict, or on account of a quasi-contract, he has never con- 
 sented to be bound at all. 
 
 Nay, more, there are certain cases in which the law fixes him 
 with liability although his will has not intervened at all. He 
 has neither done anything nor has he taken a benefit from any 
 act done on his behalf by another. 
 
 He is liable purely and simply because the law saj^s a man in 
 his position shall be liable. These are the anomalous cases such 
 as the obligation to pay aliment, which the codes describe as 
 obligations resulting from the law. But it is simpler and better 
 to say that all obligations are created by the law. except those 
 which the parties create for themselves by agreement. 
 
 Criticism of the term quasi-contract. 
 
 It is to be observed that the term quasi-contract does not belong- 
 to the Roman law. The Roman lawyers said only that in certain 
 circumstances there was an obligation which arose quasi ex con- 
 tractu, but the noun quasi-contr actus was coined by the later 
 civilians. 
 
 It was used, however, at least as early as 1480. (Gloss, ad 
 Inst. 3. 21.) 
 
 Prevot de la J amies, a French lawyer whose work was pub- 
 lished in 1750, speaks of quasi-contracts in a way that suggests 
 that it was not in his day a recognised term of the French law. 
 He says, on les nomme qiuasPconirats dans le droit Romain. 
 On pourrait parmi nous Irs appeler conventions presumecs. 
 (Principes de la jurisprudence francaise, 2, p. 354.) 
 
 But the term quasi-contrat and the analogous term quasi-delit 
 were in familiar use before the compilation of the Code Napoleon. 
 
144 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 / They were adopted in that work and arc constantly employed 
 by French writers. It would be pedantic to take exception to a 
 terminology so long- accepted, were it not that it is really mis- 
 leading-. (Sec Holland, Jurisprudence, 10th ed. p. 238, note 2. ) 
 
 But the fact is that there is no true analogy between a contract 
 and a so-called quasi-contract. The essence of contract is consent. 
 
 How can a relation in which the parties are bound without 
 consent bear any resemblance to a contract? The traditional 
 explanation was that in the quasi-contract the consent was pre- 
 sumed by a legal fiction, just as Prevot de la Jannes, in the 
 passage just cited, calls the quasi-contracts conventions presumees. 
 But this is clearly unsound; the law cannot go the length of pre- 
 suming an impossibility. And it surely cannot say that a person 
 is bound upon the fiction that he has consented, when he would 
 not have been bound if he had in fact consented. If the law says, 
 as it does, that a person incapable of giving consent can be bound 
 by the quasi-contract, it is idle to say that the liability arises 
 from presumed contract. If I prop up the house of a lunatic he 
 must reimburse me, though he could not have bound himself by 
 contract to do so. The term quasi-contract, as used in the French 
 law, denotes the eases in which the obligation arises from a lawful 
 and voluntary act. (C. C. F. 1371; C. C. Q. 1041.) 
 
 Les quasi-contrats sont les faits purement volontaires de 
 Vhom'me, dont il resulte un engagement quelomique envers un tiers, 
 et quelquefois un engagement reciproque des deux parties. 
 (C.C. F. 1371; C. C. Q. 1041.) 
 
 The French article says it is a voluntary act which creates the 
 obligations. 
 
 And another article says that there is. in a quasi-contract always 
 a fait personnel. Neither of these statements gives us a satis- 
 factory criterion. (C. C. F. 1370; C. C. E. 144/205.) 
 
 It is not because the act is voluntary that the obligation arises. 
 Otherwise, how can we explain the fact that in many cases it is 
 not the person who does the voluntary act who is bound, but 
 another person who does nothing at all ? 
 
 In the quasi-contract of gestion d'affaires the person who inter- 
 venes and does something for th'e benefit of another incurs certain 
 liabilities, and we may say, if we like, that they arise from his 
 voluntary act in interfering in somebody else's business. But 
 wo cannot explain in this way the obligation of the person for 
 whom he has acted. There has been no voluntary act on his part. 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 145 
 
 and to say that ho is bound by the voluntary act of another to 
 whom he has given no authority to art for him, is merely to say 
 that the obligation is created by law. (See Planiol, 2, n. 811.; 
 There might be some convenience in the use of the term quasi- 
 contract if it could be made to cover all the obligations which 
 arise without: — 
 
 (a) agreement, or 
 
 (b) fault. 
 
 But it is in fact impossible to make this term cover all the 
 cases, as is shown by the fact that the oodifiers have felt themselves 
 obliged to form an additional group of obligations described as 
 resulting from the law solely. 
 
 This is unavoidable, because there are cases in which an obliga- 
 tion arises without any fait personnel. 
 
 The term quasi-contract is not at all a happy one, because it 
 suggests an analogy with contract where no analogy exists, and 
 because it conceals the fact that the liability arising from the 
 so-called quasi-contracts is, after all, created by the law solely. 
 
 But the term is so firmly established in the French law that it 
 would be pedantry to avoid it, and no serious difficulty can arise, 
 from its use if we bear in mind the foregoing criticism. 
 
 Although the Egyptian Code does not use the term, the courts 
 employ it, and in this they merely follow the universal usage. 
 (See C. A. Alex. 1 dec. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 64.) 
 
 German Code avoids term quasi-contract. 
 
 The German Code, like the Egyptian Code in this respect, does 
 not use the term quasi-contract at all. It gives no express classi- 
 fication of the sources of obligations. 
 
 But' its plan is to divide obligations into three groups accord- 
 ing as they arise — 
 
 (a) From contract, or 
 
 (b) From an unlawful act, or 
 
 (c) From unjust enrichment and from certain other special 
 causes. (Arts. 305, 823, 812, 122, 307. See Saleilles, Thearie 
 Generate cle VObligation, 3rd ed. p. 449; Schuster, German CivU 
 Law, p. 350.) 
 
 w. — vol. ii. -^ 
 
146 THE LAW OP OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Distinction between quasi-contract and implied contract. 
 
 A quasi-contracl must not be confounded with an implied con- 
 trad. By an implied or tacit contract is meant a contract in 
 which the consent of one party or of both of them has not been 
 expressed in words, but is inferred from conduct. 
 
 As we have seen in speaking of the formation of contract, there 
 are many cases in which a party is held to have given his consent, 
 although he has not said so in express terms. 
 
 In regard to mandate, for instance, such cases are particularly 
 i ommon. If a man stands by, and allows another to do something 
 on his behalf, without making any protest, this implies as a rule 
 that he accepts this other as his agent in that regard, and it would 
 be a fraud upon the public to allow him to turn round and re- 
 pudiate his liability. (See C. A. Alex. 29 dec. 1898, B. L. J. 
 XI, 77.) 
 
 So in France the husband is held, in the general case, to have 
 given to his wife a mandate to purchase necessaries for the house- 
 hold, because he usually leaves to her the duty of buying things for 
 the family. (Planiol, 3, nos. 1099 seq. ; Colin et Capitant, 1, 
 p. 625; B.-L., Lc Courtois et Surville, Contrat du Manage, 1, 
 n. 078: U. N. C. C. art. 1420, n. 21.) There is not the same 
 presumption among Mohammedans, seeing that the purchasing 
 for the household is commonly done by the husband. 
 
 But in all such cases where we say that there is an implied 
 contract, the parties have given their consent, and the difference 
 between the implied contract and the express contract is merely 
 a difference as to the manner in which their consent has been 
 manifested. But in' a quasi-contract the obligation does not arise 
 from consent at all. A party may become liable without his 
 knowledge, and even '-without having the capacity to give consent 
 if he had wanted to do so. 
 
 Proof of quasi-contracts. 
 
 Tin Egyptian Code does not contain any separate rule as to the 
 proof of quasi-contracts; it merely has the general rule laid down 
 in C. C. E. 215 280. 
 
 The French Code appears to say that proof by witnesses is 
 always admissible as to obligations arising from quasi-contracts, 
 for the reason that it was impossible for the creditor in such cases 
 to procure proof in writing. (C. C. F. 1348.) 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 147 
 
 This article seems at first sight to lay down this rule as appli- 
 cable to every case of obligation arising- from quasi-contract, and, 
 in this respect, to place the proof of quasi-contract in the same 
 position as the proof of quasi-delict or of delict. For it says 
 proof by writing is not to be required when it was impossible to 
 procure it, and then it goes on to say, Cette exception s applique 
 mix obligations qui naissent des quasi-contracts et des delits on 
 qaiisi-cUlits. 
 
 But it is generally admitted in the French law that the article 
 must not be interpreted to mean that proof by witnesses of an 
 obligation arising from a quasi-contract is competent when the 
 party might have procured proof in writing. It is a question, 
 therefore, of circumstances. 
 
 Seeing that the obligations here arise simply from facts, it is 
 natural that the facts should be capable of being proved by wit- 
 nesses. In the case of gestion d'affaires, for example, the person 
 whose affairs have been managed cannot obviously be expected 
 to procure proof in writing of the acts done by the geramt, nor 
 can the gerant be expected to have proof in writing of all that 
 he has done. If he has rendered personal services, he can prove 
 these by witnesses, although the amount claimed is above 1,000 
 P. T. " (C. A. Alex. 23 fevr. 1889, B. L. J. XI, 133- Req. 
 2 mai 1892, D. 93. 1. 316; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2623.)} 
 
 On the other hand, when the gerant has dealt with third parties 
 and has paid sums of money to them, or has made contracts with 
 them, there is nothing to prevent him from obtaining receipts and 
 proof in writing of the obligations which he has contracted, and 
 accordingly in such cases he will not be allowed to make proof by 
 witnesses. (Demolombe, 30, n. 156; B.-L. ,et Barde, 4, n. 2624; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1348, n. 55; Cass. 6 fevr. 1878, D. 78. 1. 167.) 
 
 This conclusion has been criticised by Canadian writers on the 
 ground that receipts by the third parties with whom the gerant 
 has dealt would not in any case be proof in writing against the' 
 person on whose behalf it is alleged the gestion was made. 
 
 It would only be proof of payment by the gerant, and would 
 not prove on whose behalf he made it. (Mignault, Droit Civil 
 Canadien, 6, p. 74 in fine.) 
 
 But this criticism does not appear to be well founded. The 
 receipt or other proof in writing which the gerant might procure 
 does not make complete evidence of the debt due to him by the 
 person for whom he has acted, but it establishes certain fails 
 juridiques which need to be proved as the basis of his claim for 
 
 10 (2) 
 
148 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 reimbursement. A.8 lie has not been hindered by circumstances 
 from procuring a writing, the prohibition of proof by witnesses 
 applies to this case. In the case of the quasi-contract arising 
 from a payment not due it is admitted on all hands that proof by 
 witnesses is not competent, for the person paying ought to have 
 got, and could have got. a receipt. (Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8. 
 p. 345.) 
 
 In the Egyptian law the ease is clearer, because the code does 
 not mention quasi-contracts as being an exception to the rule, 
 and says merely that the parties must prove by writing " provided 
 they have not been prevented by circumstances from obtaining a 
 document." (C. C. E. 215/280.) 
 
 Negotiorum gestio or gestion d'affaires. 
 
 The French Code explains this quasi-contract in some detail, 
 and it will be best to begin by giving the French articles on the 
 subject, and then to examine how far they have been retained or 
 modified in the Egyptian Code. 
 
 Lorsque volontairement on gere Vaffaire d'autrui, soit que la 
 proprietaire connaisse la gestion, soit qu'il V ignore, celui qui gere 
 contracte V engagement Incite de continues la gestion qu'il a com- 
 mencee, et <le Vachever jusqu'd ee que le proprietaire soit en flat 
 d'y pourvoir Vni-meme; il doit se charger egalement de toutes 
 les dependances tl< cette meme affaire. 
 
 II se soumet a toutes les obligations qui resulteraient d"un 
 mandat expres que lui await donne le proprietaire. 
 
 II est oblige de continue)- sa gestion, encore que le mailre vienne 
 a mourir avant que Vaffaire soit consommee, jusqu'd ee que 
 Vheritier ail pu en prendre la direction. 
 
 II est tenu d'apporhr a in gestion de I' affaire tons les soins d'un 
 bon pere de famille. 
 
 Neanitvoins les circonstances qui Von conduit a se charger <l< 
 Vaffaire, peuvent autoriser le juge a, moderer les dommages el 
 interets qui resulteraient des fautes ou de la negligence du 
 gerant. 
 
 Le maitre dont Vaffaire u ete Men aelministree, doit rempiir les- 
 engagements que le gerant a oontractes en son nom, Vinclemniser 
 de tons les engage minis personnels qu'il a pris, et lui remboursei 
 toutes les depenses utiles <>n necessaires qu'il a faites. (C. C. F. 
 arts. 1372, 1373. 1374, 1375. Cf. C. C. Q. 1043—1046.) 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 149 
 
 The French Code calls the person whose business is managed 
 by the other le maltrc or le pmprietaire, as the Roman law called 
 him the (Umiiiiux ret, because the typical case of gestion d'affaires 
 was that of the man who takes in hand the management of pro- 
 perty belonging to another, and in this way confers a benefit 
 upon its owner. 
 
 The person who interferes in another's business, and in that 
 way acquires a claim as well as incurring obligations, is called by 
 the French law the gerant, and these terms le maUre and le gerant 
 .are more eonvcni('nt"~than -any corresponding expressions in 
 English. 
 
 Analogy between gestion d'affaires and mandate. 
 
 The quasi-contract of gestion d'affaires bears a somewhat close 
 resemblance to the contract of mandate, and is in fact sometimes 
 spoken of as a sort of spontaneous mandate. (Beudant, Controls 
 et Obligations, n. 1127.) 
 
 The gerant acts without a mandate as if he had 0110; he behaves 
 as an agent, though in fact he has no authority as such. .And 
 the close connection between mandate and gestion d'affaires is 
 shown by the fact that one of them can easily be transformed into 
 the other. If the maitre becomes aware of what is being done 
 on his behalf by the gerant, and approves of it, the gerant becomes 
 from that time forward no longer a gerant but a mandatary. 
 (D. Rep. Oblig. n. 5434; B.-L. et Barde, Obligations, 4, 
 n. 2795; Cass. 25 janv. 1904, D. 1904. 1. 601, note 7.) 
 
 And, conversely, when a mandatary exceeds the limit of his 
 mandate, or continues to act after the mandate has expired, he 
 will, in many cases, be regarded as a gerant d'affaires, if he acted 
 for the benefit of his principal. (B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2797; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1372, n. 37; C. A. Alex. 15 nov. 1900, 
 B. L. J. XIII, 13.) 
 
 But in spite of the similarity in many respects between mandate 
 and gestion d'affaires there are, notwithstanding, important, 
 differences between them. The gerant has interfered in some 
 business which did not concern him. 
 
 He was not selected by the other to act as his agent and, 
 although such interference may be in some eases laudable, this 
 will only be so where there was an urgent need for it, and where, 
 in fact, it resulted in a benefit. 
 
150 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 .Accordingly, the law deals more strictly with the gerant 
 a affaires than with the mandatary in the following respects: — 
 
 (1) The mandatary can resign the mandate, but the gerant 
 who hafi begun to act must continue his management until the 
 business is completed, or until the maitre can take charge of it 
 himself. 
 
 (2) The unpaid mandatary is not answerable for his faute 
 legere, according to the Egyptian Code, and, according to the 
 French law his responsibility in regard to faults is less heavy 
 than that of a paid mandatary. (C. C. E. 521/638; C. C. F. 
 1992.) But the gerant is bound to tons le$ soins (Vun bon pere 
 de fmnille. 
 
 (3) The mandatary's powers and liabilities are strictly limited 
 to the terms of the mandate, but the gerant is bound to take charge 
 of all the accessory operations — il doit se charger egalement de 
 toutes les dependences de cette meme affaire. (C. C. F. 1372.) 
 There may be matters, not falling strictly within the business, 
 which ho began to do, which are nevertheless to be considered as 
 a necessary complement of it. (See Dall. Sapp. Oblig. n. 2266.) 
 
 (4) The mandatary may according to the contract be entitled 
 to a salary or to a commission, whereas the gerant has never a 
 right to remuneration, except, perhaps, in the very limited sense 
 which will be explained later. 
 
 (5) The obligations made by the mandatary in the name of the 
 mandant do not bind the mandatary but bind the mandant, unless- 
 the mandatary exceeded his authority. But the obligations 
 entered into by the gerant bind the maitre only if the business 
 done by the germt was well done — si V affaire a ete bien adminis- 
 tree. (Infra, p. 154.) 
 
 (6) The mandatary can always recover his expenses from the 
 mandant unless there was fault on his part, whether the business 
 was successful or not. But the right of the gerant to recover his- 
 expenses is limited to the amount by which the maitre was 
 benefited. 
 
 Conditions of gestion d'affaires. 
 
 There is a gestion d'affaires whenever one man voluntarily does 
 some business for another without a mandate. The classical case 
 is that of the man who repairs his neighbour's house which is 
 standing empty, there being an urgent need for the interference, 
 .Hid no means of communicating with the owner. But it is not 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 151 
 
 necessary to the conception of gestion d'affaires that it should 
 consist in an intervention to protect property abeadj belong ing 
 to the maitre. 
 
 An interference to acquire a right for the third party, as in 
 the case of stipulation pour autnii, is also a kind of grsfion 
 d'affaires. 
 
 But it has certain rules peculiar to it which have been already 
 explained. (See B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2791: Planiol. 2. 
 n. 2274. Cf. Poitiers, 19 mars 1906, S. 1907. 2. 161: Rev. 
 Trim. 1907, p, 811.) 
 
 Is gestion confined to the doing of juridical acts? 
 
 The language of the French Code, and the general principles 
 applicable to the case, indicate clearly that by gestion is meant 
 the administration of some business. 
 
 M. Planiol says it means always the accomplishment of a 
 juridical act. (2, n. 2273, and see his note to Req. 20 dec. 
 1910, D. 1911. 1. 377.) 
 
 But this restriction is not made in the French' Code, and we 
 have no right to make it, nor is there any equitable reason for it . 
 
 In the Roman law the acte a\e gestion might just as well be a 
 material act, such as the repairing of a wall or the extinction 
 of a fire, as a juridical act, such as paying another's debt or 
 binding oneself to pay for work done on his property. (Girard. 
 Manuel de Droit Boynain, 5th ed. p. 625.) 
 
 And the French jurisprudence supplies examples of gestion 
 d'affaires consisting in the doing of a material act. For instance, 
 an innkeeper who takes in a workman injured by an accident 
 has a claim as a mgotiorum gestor against the employer if the 
 employer was responsible for the accident. (Req. 28 fevr. 1910. 
 D. 1911. 1. 137, and note by M. Dupuioh.) A person succeeds 
 in securing for an interdicted lunatic a greater degree of material 
 comfort and attention. (Aix, 20 dec. 1888. S. 90. 2, 25, and 
 note by M. Naquet.) A man stops a horse which is running 
 away in the public road and is a danger to the public . In so doing 
 the man suffers an injury. He has an action for indemnity 
 against the owner of the horse. (Trib. comm. Seine, 3 janv. 
 1900, S. 1902. 2. 217, and note by M. Perreau. In this sense, 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 712. So, likewise, in the German law. 
 Cosack, Lehrbuch, 6th ed. 1, p. 635.) 
 
 In Egypt there is no room for the contention that gestion 
 
152 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 implies a juridical act. The French Code by speaking of (jest ion 
 and of affaire lends some support to this view, though it ought in 
 my opinion to be rejected in the French law also. 
 
 But the Egyptian Code does not employ these terms gestion or 
 affaire at all. It says merely "the act of one person." and this 
 must cover material acts as well as juridical acts. 
 
 Is it essential that the gestion shall be unknown to the 
 
 maitre? 
 
 It would seem to be so. This was the theory of the Roman 
 law and of the old French law, and the reasons given are satis- 
 factory. The Roman law said semper qui non prohibet pro se 
 intervenire, mandare creditur, that is to say in every case where. 
 one does not prohibit another from interfering in one's affairs 
 one is taken as having given him a mandate. (D. 50. 17. 60; 
 17. 1. 6. 2, and the texts collected in Maynz, Court de Droit 
 Romain, 2, p. 476.; 
 
 Pothier says, il faut pear le quasi-contrat negotiorum gestorum 
 que celui qui a fait I 'affaire de quelqu'un, Vait faite a son insu. 
 Sans cela il u'/j a pas lieu, au quasi-co.ntr.at negotiorum gestorum; 
 oar, lor&que vous avez fait Vaffavre de quelqu'un a son vu ef a son 
 su, ou il Va souffert ou il s'y est oppose. S'il Va souffert, il est 
 cense, en soufframt que vous fissiez pour lui cette affaire, eons. 
 avoir donne im mandat tacite de la faire, et s'est le cas du contrat 
 de mandat et non celui du quasi-contrat negotiorum gestorum. 
 (Du Quasi-contrat, Negotiorum Gestorum, Appendice au contrat 
 de mandat. n. 180.) 
 
 It is hard to see how it can be otherwise. 
 
 The Quebec Code expressly follows the old rule: He ivho of 
 his. own accord assumes the management of any business of 
 another, without the knowledge of the latter, etc. (C. C. Q. 
 1043 
 
 The French Code, for very obscure reasons, changed the law by 
 saying: Lorsque volontairement on gere Vaffaire d.autrui, soit 
 que h proprietaire connaisse la gestion, soil qu'il V ignore. 
 (C. C. F. 1372. To justify the innovation thus made by the 
 French Code, the writers are .driven to draw a very fine distinction 
 between knowledge and approval. If the maitre becomes aware 
 of the gestio and has time and opportunity to stop it, but he 
 chooses to let it go on, there is a tacit mandate thereafter. 
 
 If, however, the facts lead to the conclusion that, though he 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AX ACT. 153 
 
 knows of the gestio lie submits to it, rather than approves of it, 
 the operation continues to be gestion d'affaires. 
 
 (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2795; B.-L. et Wahl, Contrats 
 Aleatoires, n. 483; Dissertation by M. Pie, in note to Alger, 
 6 mai 1896, I). 99. 2. 412. Cf. Laurent, 27, n. 384.) 
 
 Egyptian law. 
 
 The Egyptian Codes do not say expressly, as does the Quebec 
 Code, that the gestion must be without the knowledge of the 
 maitre. (C. C. E. 144/205.) 
 
 On the other hand, they leave out the words of the French Code, 
 soit que le proprietaire connaisse la gestion, soil qu'il Vignore. 
 Looking to the history of the point, and to the want of favour 
 which these words have found in France, it may well be that the 
 Eg yptian legislator omitted them intentionally, and meant to go 
 back to the old law. 
 
 In a recent case the Mixed Court of Appeal spoke of gestion 
 d'affaires as being always a Vinsu du maitre. (C. A. Alex. 
 9 fevr.,1905, B. L. J. XVII, 118.) But it was not necessary to 
 decide the point in that case. 
 
 Knowledge of incapable person is immaterial. 
 
 There is certainly one case where knowledge is consistent with 
 negotiornm gestio, namely, when the person benefited is incapable 
 of giving the mandate. (Planiol, 2, n. 2273; infra, p. 157.) 
 
 It is frequently immaterial to decide whether the case is one of 
 negotiorum gestio or of tacit mandate. 
 
 But it may be material to decide which it is on account of the 
 difference in the rules of evidence. Mandate, unless it is of a 
 commercial nature, is not capable of being proved by witnesses, 
 whereas necpi iontm gestio can be so proved. 
 
 (Guillouard, Mandat, n. 61; Douai, 11 nov. 1891, D. 92. 2. 
 352. 
 
 And there are certain other cases in which the distinction may 
 be important, some of the special rules as to mandate not ap]>lying 
 to negotiorum gestio. The claim of a mandatary against the 
 mandator does not depend on the business being successfully 
 accomplished, as the claim of the gestor does. And, again, the 
 gestor cannot throw up the management of the affair on the death 
 of the person for whom he is acting, whereas the mandatary is only 
 obliged to complete business which is urgent. C. C. F. 1373, 
 1991; C. C. Q. 1044, 1709.) 
 
154 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 
 Must be intention to act on behalf of another and benefit 
 
 resulting. 
 
 In negotiorum gestio there is always an intentional interference 
 with another's business, the result of which is that the person inter- 
 fering acts and incurs liabilities as if he were an agent, though in 
 fact he has no authority. The man who acts not in order to benefit 
 another but in his own interest, may have a claim against the other 
 by the actio cle in rem tversp, as will be explained later, but he 
 is not a riegotiorum gestor. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 
 4, n. 2794; Paris, 26 avril 1892, D. 93. 2. 175.) 
 
 It isnot inconsistent, however, with negotiorum gestio that the 
 interference should have been partly for the benefit of the person 
 interfering, and partly for the benefit of the third party. (D. 
 Bep. Oblig. n. 5404; Cass. 20 dec. 1910. D. 1911. 1. 377; 
 C A. Alex. 2 avr. 1903. B. L. J. XV, 227.) 
 
 .But there is no claim if the alleged gestor at the time of the 
 interference had no intention to seek reimbursement but intended 
 to make a gift. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2798; 
 infra, p. 159.) In most respects the gestor is treated as an agent, 
 but in some respects lie is more favourably considered. If his 
 interference was called for by circumstances and was well meant, 
 the fact that, through his want of skill, some loss resulted, will 
 not make it obligatory on the court to find him liable in full 
 damages. (C. C. F. 1374: C. C. Q. 1045.) 
 
 The whole foundation of the claim by the negotiorum gestor is 
 that the business has been well managed and that the expenses 
 were necessary or useful. 
 
 This is a condition of the action whether it is brought against 
 the maitre by the gestor or by third parties. (D. Supp. Oblig. 
 n. 2284; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2818.) 
 
 There must have been some urgency calling for the inter- 
 ference, and the action taken must have been something which the 
 person himself might reasonably have done if he had been on the 
 spot and had acted as a bonus paterfamilias. 
 
 If the neighbour repairs a house which was not worth repairing, 
 or Avhich the absent owner was intending to pull down, the money 
 has not been usefully spent. 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 155 
 
 Benefit does not need to be subsisting at date of action. 
 
 On the other hand, under the French law, if the money was well 
 spent at the time it makes no difference that the house was burnt 
 down the day afterwards. (Pothier, N,eg. Gest. n. 221 : Larom- 
 biere, art. 1375, n. 9; Planiol, 2, n. 2280.) 
 
 It is not likely that the Egyptian legislator meant to alter the 
 French law on this point. 
 
 The French Code allows the gerant to claim for his depenses 
 utiles ou necessaires. And, as we have seen, this is taken to mean 
 utiles or necessaires at the date of the expenditure . The Egyptian 
 Code says the maitre must account to. the gerant for his expenses 
 and losses up to an amount equal to the profit so obtained. (C. 
 C. E. 144/205.) 
 
 I should be inclined to think this means the profit 'obtained" 
 when the money was ispent. (In this sense, De Hults, Gestion 
 d' Affaires, n. 22.) The contrary decision would tend to prevent 
 gestion d'affaires and the law desires to encourage it . 
 
 Who may be sued by third party. 
 
 When the gemnt contracted with the third party in the name 
 of the person benefited, it is this person whom the third party 
 must sue. 
 
 For it was upon his credit and not upon that of the gerant 
 that the plaintiff relied. (D. Swpp. Oblig. n. 2286; note by 
 Planiol to D. 91. 1. 49; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2814. 
 
 But when the gerant contracted in his own name, the action is 
 against him, and he has a recourse against the person benefited. 
 (Demolombe, 31, n. 192; Laurent, 20, n. 332; Douai. 9 avr. 
 1900, D. 1901. 2.1, and note. Cf . in Quebec, Societe de Pompes 
 Funebres v. Lefebiwe, 1908, R. J. Q. 33 S. C. 296. 
 
 What is included under reimbursement? 
 
 The person benefited must indemnify the gestor for all the per- 
 sonal liabilities which he has assumed, and must account to him 
 for any expenses and losses incurred by the gestor up to the amount 
 of the profit obtained, in the sense which has been explained above. 
 (C. C. E. 144/205.) Does this include in suitable cases a reason- 
 able remuneration for the gestor' S loss of time? 
 
 It would appear that his loss of time is a Mpense, and that he 
 is entitled to a reasonable remuneration for it. (Demolombe. 31, 
 n. 174; Baudrv-Laoantinerie et Barde. 4, n. 2821.) 
 
156 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But we cannot go further. If mandate is presumably 
 gratuitous, this is true a fortiori of gestion d'affaires. A man 
 cannot create a claim for his own remuneration by an interferenee 
 which was purely spontaneous. It has been held in a Quebec 
 case, that the fact that the services rendered by the gestor involved 
 danger to him, did not entitle him to a larger indemnity. In 
 that case armed burglars had broken into a bank, and carried off 
 a thousand pounds in gold. The plaintiff, who was neither a 
 servant of the bank nor a policeman, took part in the pursuit of 
 .the burglars who were captured after a desperate struggle, and 
 eight hundred pounds of the booty was recovered. It was held 
 that the plaintiff had a legal claim only to reasonable compensation 
 for his loss of time, which was valued at one pound. 
 
 The facts that he risked his life and that his services resulted 
 in a large benefit were irrelevant. (Wark v. People's Bank, 1900, 
 E. J. Q. 13 S. C. 486.) This case also illustrated the rule that 
 the remuneration which the gestor can claim is not to be measured 
 by the value of the benefit procured, except in the sense that he 
 can never claim more than the value of this benefit. If, at a small 
 expense to himself, he renders a great service, he can claim only, 
 to be remunerated for his small expense. 
 
 If the gerant is killed or injured in rendering the service, is 
 there a claim for reparation against the maitre 1 This is a 
 doubtful question. There is some French authority for the 
 affirmative. M. Boistel says tons les sacrifices faits par le gerant 
 d'affaires sont compris dans le sens general des mots " depenses 
 utiles ou necessaires" d,e Tart. 1375, du moment qu'une repara- 
 tion pecimiaire en est possible. Le devouement aux interets du 
 patron, qui a ete pousse jusqu'au sacrifice de la vie merite a ce 
 point de vue la qualification de depense utile ou necessaire. (Note 
 to Req. 28 oct. 1907. D. 1908. 1. 483, in fin. See B.-L. et Wahl, 
 Con/rats Aleatoires, n. 720.) The victim in that case had been 
 killed by the great volcanic eruption of 1902 in Martinique, where 
 he was acting on behalf of the defendant. The arret iste considers 
 him as a gerant, but he was regarded by the Court as a mandatary. 
 And in several French cases it has been held that a man who 
 stopped a runaway horse and was injured in so doing, had an 
 action against its owner as a negotiorum gestor. (Trib. Comm. 
 de la Seine, 3 janv. 1900, S. 1902. 2. 217, and cases cited in 
 note.) 
 
 Tin- language of the Egyptian Code, depenses et pertes subies, 
 seems equally wide. (C. C. E. 144/205.) 
 
r 
 
 OBLIGATIONS RESULTING PROM AN ACT. 157 
 
 The codes say that the gestor subjects himself to all the obliga- 
 tions which result from an express mandato. (C. ('. F. 1372; 
 C. C. Q. 1043.) They do not say that he has all the rights ol a 
 mandatary. Nevertheless, it would appear that he has a righl 
 of retention, and cannot be compelled to give up property of the 
 person benefited which is in his possession in connection with the 
 gestio, until he has b^en reimbursed. 
 
 For a right of retention is not restricted to cases in which it is 
 expressly given. It is an equitable right which exists whenever 
 there is a contractual or a quasi-contractual relation between the 
 two parties, and a debt connected with the thing retained has 
 arisen. But there must be a connection between the debt and 
 the thing retained. 1 (Guillouard, Trait e de la Retention, n. 47; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 3, p. 189; Orleans, 23 juin 1898, D. 
 99. 2. 63; Grandmoulin, Suretes Rersormelles, etc., n. 821.' 
 
 On the other hand, it would appear that the gestor has no 
 privilege, for privileges are stricti juris and not to be extended 
 by analogy. He has no right to sell the thing and pay himself 
 out of the proceeds. (Guillouard, op. cit. n. 25.) 
 
 Does the maitre need to have contractual capacity? 
 
 In a quasi-contract the obligation is not based on the consent 
 of the parties. A party may become liable even without his 
 knowledge, as in the case of negotiorum gestio, and, seeing that 
 consent is not necessary, it is immaterial that the party bound had 
 not contractual capacity. When the liability arises from the party 
 having received a benefit at the expense of another, the fact that 
 the party benefited is incapable, is no reason why he should not 
 be bound to pay for the benefit.' The principle against unjust 
 enrichment applies as well to a pupil or a lunatic as to a person 
 of full capacity. 
 
 A person altogether devoid of reason cannot by his act make 
 himself liable, for reason, at any rate to some extent, is required 
 to commit a delict or a quasi-delict. 
 
 But a man does need to be fully capable in order to bo liable 
 for delicts or quasi-delicts. A minor below the age of full capa- 
 city may have intelligence enough for this purpose. (Sourdat, 
 Responsabilite, 5th ed. 1, n. 17; Cass. 21 oct. 1901, D. 1901. 1. 
 524; D. N. C. C. art. 1382, nos. 37 seq.) 
 
 Nor can an incapable person by his act bind himself towards 
 
158 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 another by becoming a party to a contract, or as being a 
 negotiontm gestor. But when the obligation arises from the act 
 of another the person rendered liable does not need to possess 
 reason. The Code of Quebec expressly states: A person in- 
 capable of contracting may, by the quasi-contract which results 
 from tin art of cmother, be obliged towards him. (C. C. Q. 
 1042. 
 
 And though the French and the Egyptian codes do not say so, 
 there is no doubt that the law is the same. (Aubry et Rau, 
 4th ed 4. s. 441, p. 723; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2800; Guenee, 
 De la capacite de s'obliger dans les quasi-contrats, Rev. Crit. 
 v. 16, 1887. p. 337; Chambery, 13 aout 1891, D. 93. 2. 316; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1372, n. 93.) 
 
 The principle of the liability of an incapable person to pay 
 for benefits which he has received without contract will be illus- 
 trated in speaking of the action- in rem verso. 
 
 Does the gerant need to have contractual capacity? 
 
 It is maintained by some writers that it is not necessary that 
 the gerant should have capacity to contract. (Guenee, Rev. 
 ( riL. 16, 1887, p. 327 ; Larombiere, on art. 1374, n. 9 ; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1372, n. 100.; 
 
 But this opinion does not seem to be sound. A jDerson who 
 cannot bind himself by contract cannot bind himself any more by 
 a quasi-contract resulting from a voluntary act on his part. 
 
 The gerant is a sort of mandatary without a mandate; if for 
 want of capacity, he could not have accepted a mandate, or have 
 been obliged to execute it, he cannot any the more bind himself 
 by a gestion d'affaires which puts him in the same position as 
 that which would have resulted from the mandate. An incapable 
 person, therefore, who has acted as gerant, is not bound to continue 
 his management. But he will have a claim against the maitre by 
 the actio de in remverso, subject to the conditions to be explained 
 immediately, because this liability arises from the enrichment. 
 And if the gestion has resulted in the gerant receiving money or 
 money's worth, the other party will have an action against him 
 for repetition. Or if in his gestion, the incapable person has 
 committed a delit or a quasi-delit, and he possesses enough in- 
 telligence to be responsible, he will be responsible for his fault;. 
 'Bufnoir. Proprieteet Con.trat. p. 794: B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2799; 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 109 
 
 Aubn el Rau, 4th ed. 4, p. 722; Planiol, 2, u. 2278: Colin 
 et Capitant, 2, p. 713; D. N. C. C. art. 1372, n. 104.) 
 
 Examples of negotiorum gestio. 
 
 A third party who furnishes necessaries to a person whom 
 another was bound to aliment is &negotiorwm gestor for that other. 
 He pays another's debt, and is entitled to be indemnified. If the 
 furnishing was made without the knowledge of the person 
 primarily liable, the claim is strictly one of negotiorum gestio. 
 If it wa.s made with the other's knowledge, the person benefited, 
 that is, the person legally bound to aliment the other, will be 
 liable upon the theory that the person whom he was bound to 
 aliment was authorised to contract debts for necessaries upon his 
 credit. (See Pand. Frang. vo. Aliments, nos. 586 seq.; Demo- 
 lombe, 4, n. 74; Laurent, 3, n. 54; Dijon, 4 fevr. 1888, D. 89. 
 2. 243.) 
 
 But it must be borne in mind that in such cases there is no 
 ground for repetition, if the person who incurred the expenses or 
 furnished the necessaries did so from motives of affection or in- 
 terest, and without any intention of reserving a claim to be repaid. 
 It will be for the court to decide according to the circumstances, 
 whether there was the intention to reserve a claim.- (Pothier, 
 Quasi-Contrat, Neg. Gest. n. 196; Dall. Rep. vo. Oblig. n. 5400; 
 Dall. Supp. Oblig. n. 2257; Fuzier-Herman, Code Civ. Ann. 
 art. 1375, n. 73; C. A. Alex. 24 dec. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 75.) 
 
 So, where a grandmother who had supported a granddaughter 
 for a number of yea,rs, and had paid for her education, afterwards 
 sued the child's father for repetition of these expenses, it was 
 held that the facts showed that the grandmother had acted from 
 mere affection, and animo danandi, and that she had no claim for 
 repetition either against the father or against the child herself. 
 (Cass. 25 juin 1872, D. 74. 1. 16. Cf. Paris, 26 avr. 1892, 
 D. 93. 2. 175; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2798; 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Houques-Fourcade, Personnes, 3, n. 2084.) 
 
 On the same principle, if necessaries have been supplied by a 
 person who with others is under a legal obligation to supply them, 
 the facts may indicate that in supplying the necessaries he did 
 not intend to reserve a right of recourse against the other persons 
 liable, for their shares. (Paris, 26 avr. 1892, D. 93. 2. 175.) 
 
 Moreover, it must not appear that the goods were supplied on 
 the credic of the person to whom they were actually given, or there 
 will be no recourse. 
 
■ 160 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Another ease of negotiorum gestio is that where a person pays 
 the i'uneral expenses of another, and claims a recourse against the 
 person legally bound to pay such expenses. 
 
 Primarily, the succession of \\w deceased was liable. But if 
 tin' succession is unable to defray the expenses, there will be a 
 claim againsl the surviving consort, the parent or the children of 
 the deceased. (Pand. Franc, vo. Aliment*, n. 290. Cf., in 
 England, Bradskaw v. Beard, 1862, 12 C. B. N. S. 344, 133 E . R. 
 360. See American cases in Keener, Quasi-Contracts, p. 344; 
 Scott's Cases on Quasi-Contracts, pp. 292 seq. ; infra, p. 199.) 
 
 The following are miscellaneous examples of applications of 
 the principle which have been made by the Mixed Courts in 
 Egypt. 
 
 The Con sci I Sanitaire et Quarantenaire provided for the re- 
 patriation of certain pilgrims who had been shipwrecked and dis- 
 embarked at the quarantine camp. The Conseil was held entitled 
 to recover its expenses from the owners and charterers of the ship. 
 (C. A. Alex. 25 avril 1900, B. L. J. XII, 217.) ■ 
 
 The occupant a iitre gratuit ' of an immoveable belonging to 
 the State was held entitled to recover the plus-value arising from 
 the improvements which he had made at his own expense. (C. A. 
 Alex. 2 avril 1903, B. L. J. XV, 227. Cf . C. A. Alex. 13 fevr. 
 1895, B. L. J. VII, 122; C. A. Alex. 15 mai 1912, B. L. ,J. 
 XXIV, 342, for other illustrations.) 
 
 Assistance to ship in distress. 
 
 The important and common case, in which the captain of a ship 
 is called upon to give assistance to a vessel in distress, is dealt 
 with in the French jurisprudence in a manner difficult to reconcile 
 with principles. 
 
 The French law applies to this case the technical name of 
 assistfmoe. It does not use here fhe term SM Mefyi ge, because the 
 matter of sauvetage is regulated bv art. 27 de VOrdonnance de 
 1681. 
 
 This ordormance gives the salvor a right to one-third of the 
 effects salved, but in order to enjoy this right there must have 
 been a salvage in tin Btrid sense of the term. One of the essential 
 conditions is that the vessel must have been found after it had 
 been abandoned by its crew. It has been held that even the 
 presence of one sailor on board is enough to exclude the idea of 
 
OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM AN ACT. 161 
 
 salvage. (Dall. Repertoire Pratique, vo. Droit Maritime, n. 
 1303.) 
 
 Assistance is a different case from this. It consists in render- 
 ing aid to a vessel in peril. This aid may be rendered, of course, 
 after an agreement as to the remuneration, and the question 
 whether this remuneration can be reduced if it is extortionate has 
 been discussed under the head of violence. {Supra, I, p. 302., 
 The case with which we are now concerned, however, is where no 
 agreement has been made as to the amount to be paid. 
 
 If we adopt the view that mandate is not confined to the per- 
 formance of juridical acts, we may say that the captain who gave 
 the assistance is a mandatary if his aid was asked for, or was 
 tacitly agreed to. But, as will be explained presently, it is gene- 
 rally held that mandate implies representation. Where the cir- 
 cumstances do not indicate any agreement, even tacit, we may 
 say that the captain who "assists" is a person who confers a 
 benefit in circumstances such as give him a claim by the actio de 
 in rem verso. 
 
 But whether the case is one of mandate or of gestion d'affaires 
 he will be entitled to recover his depenses utiles. But this limit 
 of the right does not satisfy the equities of the situation. The 
 rendering of services of this kind is frequently a hazardous opera- 
 tion. It may be necessary to run great risk, and, after all, the 
 operation may be unsuccessful. If it were the law that the salvor 
 could recover only depenses utiles it would give little encourage- 
 ment to captains to render such services, whereas, it 'seems that 
 the law ought to do what it can to encourage them. 
 
 The French jurisprudence is more liberal in cases of assistance 
 en mer than the strict rules of gestion d'affaires would permit. 
 In the first place, it allows the payment of a remuneration as well 
 as of expenses. Le muveteur qui, a defaut des conditions pre- 
 scrites par Vart. 27 de Vordonnance de 1681, ne peut, conforme- 
 ment a celle-ci, reclamer le tiers des effets sauves, a neanmoin* 
 le droit, s'il a assiste un navire en peril, de reclamer, outre le 
 remboursement de ses depenses, une indemnite pour assistance et 
 perle de temps. (Rennes, '26 juillet 1906, D. 1908. 2. 237.) 
 
 In the second place, French courts award a remuneration 
 although the assistance may have turned out to be useless, owing 
 to circumstances for which the captain of the salving vessel was 
 not responsible. (Dall. Hep. Pratique, vo. Droit Maritime, n. 
 1323.) 
 
 If, for example, the ship had been taken in tow, and had after- 
 w.— VOL. II. 11 
 
162 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 wards broken loose and sunk, it would be hard to see on the prin- 
 ciple of negotiorum gestio that any benefit had been procured. 
 
 The Convention of Brussels of 23 Sept. 1910, formulated a 
 number of rules upon the subject, and a projet de loi was depose 
 on 26 juillel 1913, to embody these rules in the French law. 
 But this matter does not concern us here. (See Lyon-Caen et 
 Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 6, n. 1066; Dall. 
 Rep. Prat. vo. Droit Maritime, nos. 1317 seq.;. Vermond, Manuel 
 de Droit Maritime, 4th ed. p. 368; and for the closely analogous 
 rules applied in the English law, see Kennedy, Law of Civil 
 Salvage, 2nd ed. p. 31 ; Carver, Carriage of Goods by Sea, 5th ed. 
 s. 333.) But in the English law the rule is "No success, no 
 salvage," unless, in the circumstances, it is possible to imply a 
 promise to pay. (The Benlarig, 1888, 14 P. D. 3, 58 L. J. 
 A dm 24; Kennedy, I.e.; Carver, I.e.) 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence. 
 
 There is very little Egyptian jurisprudence upon the subject, 
 but it appears that so far the courts have applied the letter of the 
 law strictly. 
 
 En droit mixte, la question du sauvetage et de la prime due 
 au sauveteur, ne pent etre reglee, vu le silence de la loi sur la 
 matiere, que d'apres Vart. 205 du code civil, aux termes duquel 
 le fait d'une persanne qui a procure intentiomiellement un benefice 
 a uup autre personne oblige cette derniere a tenir compte des 
 depmses et pertes subies par la premiere jusqiid concurrence du 
 profit obtenu. (C. A. Alex. 12 mai 1892, B. L. J. IV, 235.) 
 
 If we can regard the relation between the salvor and the captain 
 of the ship in peril as one of tacit mandate there would be no 
 difficulty. The Egyptian law allows the judge to control the 
 remuneration of a mandatary, and the court has power enough to 
 deal in an equitable way with a case which can be considered as 
 one of mandate. (C. C. E. 514/628.) 
 
 But the prevailing view in France is that a mandatary is a 
 person who represents another for performing juridical acts only. 
 (B.-L. et Wahl, Contrats Aleatoires, n. 361, and n. 363; Planiol, 
 2, n. 2231; dissertation of M. Labbe to Req. ler fevr. 1891, 
 S. 1893 1. 497; D. N. C. C. art. 1984, n. 17. Cf., in Egypt, 
 Grandmoulin, Contrats, n. 913.) There is, however, a reaction 
 against this view which makes it impossible to consider certain pro- 
 fessional men such as doctors and architects as being mandataries. 
 
 (See B.-L. et Wahl, op. cit . n. 363; Colin et Capitant, 2, 
 p. 699; Agen, 4 mars 1889, D. 90. 2. 281, note by M. Glasson.) 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 163 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 
 
 One of the most famous maxims of the Roman law is Jure 
 naturre cequum est neminem cum alterius detrimento et iniuria 
 fieri locupletiorem. (Dig. 50. 17. 206.) That is to say, it is 
 contrary to the law of nature and equity that one man should be un- 
 justly enriched to the prejudice of another. And this maxim, in its 
 French form: Nul ne doit s'enrichir injustement aux depens 
 d'autrui, is frequently cited toy French writers and French judges 
 as an indisputable principle of the French law. The older writers 
 were content to speak of it as a rule of natural equity which the 
 courts had the power to apply in the absence of another remedy. 
 (See Beaumanoir, Coutumes de Beauvoisis, ed. Salmon, ch. 20, 
 p. 302, and other writers cited by M. Loubers in Rev. Crit. 1912, 
 p. 399.) 
 
 For example, Pothier, in explaining that a married woman 
 who has contracted a loan without the authorisation of her husband 
 is bound to repay it if it has. turned to her profit, says that, in 
 this case, the contract of loan is null, because in the French law, 
 the material authorisation is indispensable, but that son obliga- 
 tion est done produite par la loi naturelle seule, qui ne permet 
 pas qu( quelqu'un senrichism aux depens d'autrui. (Oblig. 
 n. 123.) 
 
 And the same writer, in another place, deals with' the difficulty 
 which arises when A has done something for the benefit of B 
 contrary to the formal injunctions of B. In this case, Pothier 
 says that A cannot have an action as a negotiorum gestor, but 
 that, nevertheless, he will have an action for repayment of that 
 which has turned to the profit of B, because in the French law 
 natural equity is in itself sufficient foundation for an action. 
 Or, brsque vous profitmz d'wqe affmp que fai frnte, quoique 
 contre votre demise, pour vous faire du bien malgre vous, requite 
 naturelle, qui ne permet pas de s'enrichir aux depens d'autrui, 
 
 11 (2) 
 
164 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 vous oblige a niindonniser de ce qiiil men a coute, jusqu'a con- 
 currence du profit que vous en retirerez. (Pothier, Du Quasi- 
 contrat negotiorum gestorum, n. 182.) 
 
 Modern authorities, likewise, state the broad rule against unjust 
 enrichment as being a rule of natural equity which must be con- 
 sidered to form part of the French law. (B.-L. et Barde, 4, 
 n. 2849 ; 11; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 6, p. 426; Cass. 15 juin 
 1892, D. 92. 1. 596.) 
 
 In the case cited the Chambre des Requites stated the principle 
 very broadly indeed. Speaking of the action de in rem verso 
 they said: Attendu que cette action derivant du principe d'equite 
 qui defend de s'enrichir au detriment d'autrui, et n' ay ant ete 
 reglementee par aiicun texte de nos lois, son exercice n'est soumis 
 a aucune condition determinee ; — Qu'il suffit, pour la rendre re- 
 ceivable, que le demandeur attegue et offre d'etablir V existence d'un 
 avantage qu'il await, par un sacrifice ou un fait personnel, pro- 
 cure a celui contre lequel il agit. . ■ 
 
 But it is undeniable that there are many cases in which one 
 person derives a benefit from the action of another without being 
 thereby placed under any legal obligation to pay for it. If there 
 is in front of my house a neglected piece of vacant land which 
 belongs to me, the dirty and disorderly condition of this land, 
 and the uses made of it by the public, may be a cause of annoyance 
 to my neighbours, although not to such a degree as to give them 1 
 a right to claim damages against me. And if I should take this 
 land into my garden, so that the windows of my neighbours' 
 houses enjoy a beautiful instead of a disagreeable prospect, the 
 value of their property might be considerably increased. But, 
 even if this were so, I should not have any action against my 
 neighbours to compel them to pay me for the benefit which they 
 had received. 
 
 If a new railway is constructed in a district which before then 
 was far removed from any market for its produce, the property 
 of the farmers in this district may be doubled in value. But 
 the railway-company cannot make them pay for this benefit. 
 
 If, in order to prevent inundations, I execute works on the 
 bank or in the bed of a river which borders my property, this may 
 benefit my neighbours as well as myself, but I cannot make them 
 pay their share, unless there is some special law which says so. 
 (Dall. Rep. Oblig. n. 5403.) 
 
 If a third party does work which improves a property hypothe- 
 cated in favour of A, this increases the value of A's security, but 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSCK 165 
 
 it does not give the third party an action against A. (So hold in 
 a Quebec case, Wallbridge v. Far well and Ont. Car Ct/., 1890, 
 18 Canadian Supreme Court Reports, 1.) 
 
 In the same way, it is not enough for a person who has lent 
 money to show that the loan has indirectly benefited a third person. 
 The lender has dealt only with the borrower, and he has not 
 directly augmented the estate of the third party. (Douai, 9 avril 
 1900, D. 1901. 2. 1.) 
 
 A sister keeps her brother's house for 10 years, and thereby 
 saves him the expense of a house-keeper. She had no intention 
 to make a claim for her services. If she changes her mind, and 
 sends in a bill for them, the brother is not legally bound to pay 
 it. (See infra, p. 182.) 
 
 The lessee of a house makes improvements in it. At the end 
 of the lease the lessor is not bound to pay for the plus-value. A 
 person buys a quantity of wine for which he does not pay. He 
 gives the wine to a third party. The wine-merchant cannot sue 
 the third party. (Trib. Seine, 22 fevr. 1913; Gaz. Pal. 29 mai 
 1913; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 409.) 
 
 Such illustrations might be multiplied, but they are enough to 
 show that we cannot say that every person who has received a 
 benefit from another without contract must pay for it. If it is 
 the rule of the law that he must pay for it in some cases, we 
 must find some criterion for distinguishing these cases from the 
 others. This is by no means an easy thing to do. Many attempts 
 to formulate the principle upon the subject have been made in 
 recent years, both by the doctrine and in the jurisprudence. But 
 numerous points are still controversial. (See, especially, Loubers, 
 H., in Revue Critique, 1912, p. 396, and p. 462; Ripjort et Teis- 
 seire, Essai d'une theorie de V enrichissement sans cause en Droit 
 Francois, Revue trim, de droit civil, 1904, p. 727; Bartin, E., 
 in Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 354, notes 7 seq.; Vergniaud, E., 
 L' enrichissement sans cause, Paris, 1916; and see the bibliography 
 there; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, nos. 2849, 11 seq.; note of 
 Bourcart, G., to Cass/ 8 fevr. 1909, S. 1911. 1. 313, with the 
 references; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 403; and the references in 
 Sirey, Table, 1901—1910, vo. Obligations en general, nos. 64 
 seq.) 
 
166 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Special applications of principle in French and 
 Egyptian Codes. 
 
 Neither the French nor the Egyptian Code contains a single- 
 article dealing expressly with the rule against unjust enrichment. 
 But the codes make numerous special applications of the principle. 
 
 He who receives that which is not due to him is bound to 
 restore it. (C. C. E. 145/206; C. C. F. 1376; infra, p. 187.) 
 
 If a man builds, with his own materials, upon another's land, 
 and the owner of the land elects to retain the buildings, he must 
 pay for them, subject to certain conditions. (C. C. E. 65/90- 
 
 C. C. F. 555.) 
 
 If a debtor pays his debt to a creditor who has not the neces- 
 sary capacity to receive the payment, the debt is extinguished so 
 far as the payment enures to the benefit of the creditor . (C . C . F . 
 1241. See C. C. E. 166/229.) 
 
 If a contract is rescinded by an incapable person on the ground 
 of his want of capacity, the incapable person must account for the 
 profit which he has received. (C. C. E. 131/191; C. C. F. 
 1312; Cass. 23 fevr. 1891, D. 92. 1. 29; Paris, 20 janv. 1904, 
 
 D. 1906. 2. 25.) 
 
 One important application of this rule is when a contract made 
 by a moral person is rescinded, because it was outside the powers 
 of the moral person. (See supra, I, p. 350.) 
 
 A corporation exists only for certain purposes, and it can no 
 more enter into a contract beyond its powers than if it had no 
 existence. Indeed, with respect to such contracts, the corporation 
 may be said to have no existence. 
 
 This principle is called in the French law the principle of 
 speciality. 
 
 A. toutes personnes morales la capacite juridique n'est concedee 
 qu'en vue d'une destination precise st dans les limites de la sphere 
 d'action qui lew est assignee par les his, les reglements ou les 
 statuts. (Ducrocq, Droit Administratif, 7th ed. 6. n. 2197; 
 Michoud, Persotmalite Morale, 2, pp. 142 seq., 177. See for the 
 same principle in the English law, Halsbury, Laws of England, 
 Contracts, p. 391; ibid,., Corporations, p. 359; Ashburu Rail way 
 Co. v. Uiche, 1875, L.B.7H.L. 653, 44 L. J. Ex. 185.) 
 
 But this rule is not intended to enable corporations to cheat 
 the public. The corporation may plead that it is not bound by 
 its contracts, and that the other party had himself to blame and 
 was bound to know the capacity of those with whom he contracted. 
 
ACTIO DK IN REM VERSO. 167 
 
 But if the corporation repudiates the transaction, it must account 
 for the benefits it has received, or give back what it has obtained 
 from the other party eo far as this is in its hands, or so far as 
 it has been applied for any beneficial purpose for which the cor- 
 poration might have come under liability by contract. 
 
 This has been applied in cases where a municipality has ordered 
 things without proper authorisation. (Chambery, 13 aout 1891, 
 D. 93. 2. 31.6; D. N. C. C. art. 1372, n. 96; Laurent, 20, 
 n. 339 Cf. Cass. 31 juill. 1895,©. 95. 1. 391; supra, I, p. 352.) 
 The details do not belong to this place. (See in the common law, 
 Keener, Quasi-Contracts, p. 272; and American cases in Pollock, 
 Contracts, 3rd American ed. p. 142.) 
 
 If a partner in a partnership contracts in his own name with a 
 third person, he does not bind the other partners, but under the 
 Egyptian Code, the third person has a right of action against each 
 of them for the amount of his share in the profits arising from the 
 operation. (C. C. E. 444/541.) 
 
 Upon this point the French law is different. (C. C. F. 1864; 
 B.-L. et Wahl, Societe, n. 334; D. N. C. C. art. 1864, n. 24.) 
 
 And, seeing that the other party relied upon the personal credit 
 of the partner, the French rule is reasonable enough. If a partner 
 contracts in the name of the partnership, but without authority 
 to do so, and a benefit_r-esults to the partnership, the otheX-partners 
 are liable each for his share,'to the extent of this profit, to the third 
 person who contracted with the partner. (C. C. E. 444/541: 
 De Hults, Rep. vo. Societe, n. 71; C. C. F. 1864; Cass. 12 mars 
 1850, S. 1850. 1. 257, D. 1850. 1. 86.) 
 
 If the depositary has spent money for the preservation of the 
 thing deposited, the depositor must repay him. (C. C. E. 
 488/596; C. C. F. 1948.) 
 
 In the mercantile law general average losses are supported by 
 contribution in the manner explained later. (Egyptian Code of 
 Maritime Commerce, 237; C. Com. F. 400; infra, p. 172.) 
 
 The principle against unjust enrichment is recognised in other 
 articles of the codes, but these will suffice, and, although no general 
 rule is found in the code, it is commonly admitted that the prin- 
 cipl underlying the provisions Jabove cited is a general one, and 
 must be applied by the courts in analogous cases. (Aubry et Ban, 
 5th ed. 9, p. 355; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2849, 11.) 
 
 It underlies many articles in the codes. For example, we may 
 base upon this principle the right which a sub-contractor has to 
 bring a direct action against the employer of the principal con- 
 
168 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 tractor. (C. C. E. 414/506. See C. A. Alex. 30 mai 1901, 
 P.. L. J XIII, 313: C. A. Alex. 27 mars 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 
 '•2 1*3: Grandmoulin, Controls, n. 634.) 
 
 The French Code is wider than the Egyptian. (C. C. F. 1798. 
 See Solus, H., L' Action Direete, these, 1914, p. 228, where the 
 case is treated as an example of enrichissement sans cause.) 
 
 In the Egyptian law, as already mentioned, some difficulty is 
 created by the codes containing only a single article stating a rule 
 which may be interpreted in a sense which does not quite agree 
 either with the rules of the French law as to gestion d'affaires or 
 with those of the action de in rem verso. (C. C. E. 144/205; 
 supra, p. 141.) 
 
 But, in all probability, the Egyptian legislator did not intend 
 to change the French law as to gestion d'affaires, and in saying 
 nothing about the action de in rem verso, he merely follows the 
 example of the French Code. 
 
 The name actio de in rem verso. 
 
 The action by which the plaintiff, whose allegation is that the 
 defendant has been justly enriched at his expense, sues for resti- 
 tution, or, if that be impossible, for payment of the value of that 
 which has passed from him to the defendant, is commonly spoken 
 of in the French law as the action de in rem verso. But the 
 action which goes b} r that name in the French law has a much 
 wider scope than the actio de in rem verso of the Roman law. In 
 the Roman law, the actio de peculio et de in rem verso was the 
 action against a paterfamilias brought by a person who had con- 
 tracted with a filiusfamilias, when the filiusfamilias had acted 
 without authority express or implied. The liability of the pater- 
 familias was limited in this case to the amount of the pecidium, 
 unless the plaintiff could show that the paterfamilias had himself 
 benefited by the contract, in which case he was liable to the extent 
 of this benefit , and this amount which had turned to his profit was 
 spoken of as having been in rem versum. (Dig. 15. 3; Girard, 
 Manuel, 0th ed. p. 669.) 
 
 But the action in the Roman law which bears the closest analogy 
 to the French action is the remdictio sine causa, and this must 
 certainly be regarded as the source of the French action de in rem 
 verso. See, as to the Roman action, Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 
 614: Girard, L'histoire de la condictio, d'apres M. Pernice, Nou- 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO, 169 
 
 velle Revue Historique, 1895, p. 408. Cf. Colin et Oapitant, 
 2, p. 404; Aubry et liau, 5th ed. 9, p. 304, note 7.) 
 
 Miscellaneous illustrations from the French jurisprudence. 
 
 Seeing that the codes do not help us to define the limits of the 
 action to prevent unjust enrichment, and seeing also that there is 
 so much controversy among recent writers as to the principles 
 which govern the matter, it may be convenient first to give a 
 number of illustrations from the jurisprudence, both of cases in 
 which the claim has been admitted, and of cases in which it has 
 been rejected by the courts. We will afterwards endeavour to 
 extract the principles from them. 
 
 A married woman by the French law cannot contract a loan 
 without the authorisation of her husband. But if she does so she 
 cannot demand rescission of the contract when the money has 
 turned to her profit, and the creditor can sue her by the actio de in 
 rem verso up to that amount. fCass. 26 avril 1900, S. 1901. 
 1. 193.) 
 
 According to the French law, a wife has a tacit mandate to 
 purchase necessaries for the household. But this mandate may be 
 withdrawn by the husband, and according to most French autho- 
 rities, it is withdrawn if the husband gives the wife a regular 
 allowance for the expenses of the household. (B.-L. et Wahl, 
 'Mcmdat, n. 484, and authorities in Sirey, Table Dec&nnah, 1901 — 
 1910, s. v. Autorisation de femme mariee, n. 12.) 
 
 But, assuming that this view is correct, and that the mandate 
 has been withdrawn, either in this way or in another, the husband 
 will still be liable to third parties who have contracted with the 
 wife to the extent to which he has profited by the things which 
 they have supplied. (B.-L. Le Courtois et Surville, Control de 
 Mariage, 3rd ed. 1, n. 502; D. Rep. Control de Manage, n. 1014, 
 note 3; Paris, 30 nov. 1899, D. 1900. 2. 105. See Trib. Seine, 
 10 dec. 1901, et 6 janv. 1902, D. 1904. 2. 238, and the note.) 
 
 And the same principle applies in the case where the wife had a 
 tacit mandate but exceeded the mandate by purchasing things 
 which were not necessary. (Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 5, s. 509, 
 note 55; D. N. C. O. art. 1420, n. 27.) 
 
 Under recent French legislation, a commune is entitled to charge 
 a rent for the priest's house or presbyter e. And where, after the 
 passing of the law, a priest lived in the house for some time without 
 a lease, it was held that the commune could claim an indemnity 
 
170 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 upon the principle de in rem verso. (Trib. de Besangon, 16 
 juillet 1908, S. 1909. 2. 1; Siiej . Table, 1901— 1910, s. v. Cultes, 
 nos. 98 seq.) 
 
 A commune obtains certain goods under a contract which is not 
 valid because it has not been approved by the prefet. The com- 
 mune is liable to the extent of the benefit which it has received. 
 (Conseil d'Etat, 28 juillet 1911, S. 1914. 3. 53. See the exten- 
 sive jurisprudence as to irregular contracts made by communes 
 cited in the note to this case; Hauriou, Droit Administratif , 8th 
 ed. p. 479; and the note by M. Bartin in Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 9, p. 363, note 13 ter.) 
 
 A genealogist, who makes it a business to discover heirs and to 
 inform them of their rights to a succession, has a right to bring an 
 action for his expenses iand for remuneration for his services, if 
 the information given by him has resulted in a profit. (Poitiers, 
 2 dec. 1907, D. 1908. 2. 332.) 
 
 If the defendant has enjoyed the use of a moveable or of an 
 immoveable which belongs to the plaintiff, and this has not been 
 in virtue of any contract, he must pay for the benefit. (Req. 
 9 nov. 1904, D^ 1905. 1. 489; Besangon, 9 dec. 1908, S. 1909. 
 2.1.) 
 
 If the plaintiff has spent money on the preservation or ameliora- 
 tion of property, moveable or immoveable, belonging to the defen- 
 dant, and this has been done without any contract and was not 
 intended as a gift, the defendant must pay to the extent of the 
 benefit ho has received. (Rouen, 25 juin 1904, D. 1906. 2. 191; 
 Paris, 6 aout 1850, D. 1854. 5. 483; Req. 16 juillet 1890, S. 
 1894. 1. 19; Bordeaux, 7 aout 1900, D. 1902. 2. 375.) 
 
 The plaintiff furnished a quantity of chemical manures to a 
 farmer who was a lessee of the defendant, and the farmer did not 
 pay for the manure. Subsequently, the lease was resiliated, and the 
 crop was abandoned by the lessee to his lessor, the defendant in 
 this case; the lessor thus profited by the manure which had pro- 
 duced the crop. This is enough, according to a decision which 
 has been much canvassed, to make him liable to the plaintiff. 
 (Req. 15 juin 1892, D. 92. 1. 596, S. 93. 1. 281.) 
 
 It is true that the French Code contains an article which does 
 not occur in the Egyptian Code: Les fruits produits par la chose 
 n'appartiennent au proprietaire qu'd la charge de rembourser les 
 frais des labours, travaux et semences faits par des tiers. (C. C. 
 F. 548.) 
 
 But this article is meant to refer to the case where the owner of 
 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 171 
 
 an immoveable rev indicates it from a person who has been in pos- 
 session of it without right. (B.-L. et Chauveau, Biens, n. 291.) 
 
 The article is not meant to apply to such a case as this one, and 
 the court expressly found that the plaintiff's right did not depend 
 upon this article, but upon the general principle, nul ne pent 
 s'enrichir cm detriment cVautrui. 
 
 It is difficult to reconcile this decision with a later case decided 
 by the Chambre des RequeUs. A farmer exercised his right under 
 the lease of subletting his farm . Before that time the farmer had 
 managed the farm very badly, and had deteriorated its value. 
 The sub-lessee, on -the other hand, executed useful works which 
 diminished the deteriorations caused by his lessor. 
 
 The sub-lessee brought an action against the owner of the farm 
 for the value of the ameliorations which he had made. This action 
 was rejected by the court, and the Chambre "des Requites rejected 
 a pourvoi. The reason relied upon in the judgment was that,, 
 after giving credit to the lessee for the improvements made upon 
 the land by the sub-lessee, there was still a sum due by him to the 
 lessor. 
 
 If the lessee had himself paid for the improvements made by 
 the sub-lessee upon the land, and he had sued the lessor for re- 
 imbursement, the lessor could have pleaded in compensation the 
 claim which he had against him for the deteriorations which had 
 resulted from his bad administration. 
 
 It was inequitable that the lessor should be deprived of this 
 right by admitting the action of the sub-lessee against him. (Req. 
 23' nov. 1908, S. 1910. 1. 425. See the Note of M. Naquet.) 
 This case and the preceding one will need to be referred to again. 
 
 Another interesting group of oases in which the principle de 
 in rem verso has been applied is when, in time of war, the invading 
 army of The enemy has made requisitions upon private individuals 
 for food or other necessaries. It has repeatedly been held that the 
 commune is bound to reimburse the private person upon whom 
 such requisitions have been made. (Req. 23 fevr. 1875, S. 1875. 
 1. 267, P. 1875. p. 636; Nancy, 22 mars 1873, D. 73. 2. 141. 
 See other cases collected in M. Bartin's note to Aubry et Rau r 
 .. ^ 5th ed. 9, p. 365.) 
 
 The credit fonder, in paying off a irypothecary creditor before 
 making their loan, neglected to stipulate that they should be sub- 
 rogated in the rights of this creditor. The result was that the 
 hypothec of the credit fonder was postponed to the legal hypothec 
 of certain minors of the same immoveables. The minors thus 
 
 ■ 
 
 
172 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 gained a benefit by the action of the credit foncier, but in spite of 
 this, the Cow de "Cassation refused to admit that the credit foncier 
 had a claim based upon the principle de in rem verso. (Cass. 11 
 juill. 1889, D. 89. 1. 393, and note by M. Petiton, S. 90. 1. 97, 
 and note by M. Labbe.) 
 
 In a fire-insurance policy there was a clause providing that, in 
 the event of the buildings being damaged or destroyed, the com- 
 pany might, instead of paying the indemnity, have the buildings 
 repaired or rebuilt at its expense. The company having exer- 
 cised this option, claimed from the insured the difference in value 
 between the new buildings and the old. The claim was rejected 
 on the ground that the company a exerce ce droit d'option dans 
 son interet exclusif, a ses risques et perils. (Req. 21 juill. 1903, 
 D. 1904. 1. 181.) 
 
 Improvement on immoveable held in indivision. 
 
 One of several owners of an immoveable held in indivision has 
 works executed upon it which enure to the benefit of all the owners. 
 
 The others are legally bound to contribute, according to their 
 shares, in the cost of these works. (Req. 20 dec. 1910, D. 1911. 
 1. 377, and dissertation by M. Planiol.) 
 
 Doctrine of general average or avaries communes. 
 
 The important doctrine of the commercial law known as con- 
 tribution to general average losses, or the reglement des avaries 
 comwrmnes, rests on the same principle. In the maritime law the 
 matter is dealt with in the codes. (C. Com. P. 400; C. Com. 
 Mar E. 237.) 
 
 As defined by AIM. Lyon-Caen et Renault: — 
 
 L'avarie commune est nn dommage materiel cause volontaire- 
 ment par le capitaine, soit au navire, soit a des merchandises de 
 la cargaison, ou une depense extraordinaire faite par iui dans 
 V interet eonvmun du navire et de la cargaison, dommage ou depense 
 qui a eu un resultat utile. (Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 
 6, n. 877.) 
 
 If goods are thrown overboard to lighten the ship, and by this 
 means the vessel itself and the rest of the freight are saved, it 
 would not be fair that the owner of the goods jettisoned should be 
 the only person to suffer. He ought to bear his share, but not 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 173 
 
 more than his share, of a loss incurred in the interests of the ship- 
 owner and of the cargo-owners generally. 
 
 So if, without the fault of the captain, the coal of a steamer runs 
 out, and it is necessary in order to feed the fires to hum the wood 
 of one of the cargo-owners, there must he contribution to this as 
 an arvarie commune. (Trib. Superieur hanseatique, 18 juin 1909, 
 D. 1911 2. 28.) 
 
 Or if legal proceedings have to be taken to liberate a ship which 
 has been seized as a prize, this is a general average loss. (Cass. 
 18 janv. 1909, D. 1909. 1. 245. For the English law, see Marine 
 Insurance Act, 1906 (6 Edw. 7, c. 41), s. 66; Carver, Carriage 
 of Goods by Sea, oth eel. nos. 361 seq., Stevens, Mercantile Law, 
 5th ed. p. 438.) And so, also, though there is controversy here, 
 if the captain of a ship which is attacked by an enemy decides to 
 right, and the ship is damaged but escapes, the cargo-owners must 
 contribute. (Lyon-Caen et Eenault, Traite de Droit Commercial 
 6, n. 926.) 
 
 Such cases are not examples of gestion d'affaires. It is not a 
 case of a man spending his own money for another's benefit, but 
 of a man, who is an agent for several people, sacrificing the goods 
 of one of them for the benefit of his other principals and for his 
 own benefit. 
 
 The essential feature is a deliberate sacrifice made in the common 
 interest. (Cf. C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 
 100., 
 
 How are we to explain the principle? 
 
 Some say that it is an implied term of the contract of affreight- 
 ment. But this is a forced explanation, and, if it were the true 
 one, wo could not understand how the owner of the goods sacrificed 
 should have a direct action against the other cargo-owners who 
 have made no contract with him. It is much sounder to say that 
 the obligation to contribute to such avarivs communes is not con- 
 tractual, but quasi-contractual, and rests upon the general rule of 
 equity — nul ne doit s'enrichir injustement, cm prejudice d'autrui. 
 (Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 6, n. 870.) 
 
 Is principle of avarie commune confined to maritime law? 
 
 This being so, the principle ought to apply on land as well as 
 on sea, and in cases not covered by the commercial codes, though 
 some authorities do not admit this. 
 
 In a curious case, a diligence was attacked by four masked 
 
174 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 robbers who called on the driver to hand over the money-bags 
 which were visible at his left hand. He threw them two bags, 
 •one of which contained 2,400 francs and the other 1,500 francs, 
 and the robbers made off with their plunder. In another place in 
 the diligence were bags worth 28,000 francs which were saved. 
 
 The Court of Paris refused to make the owners of the money 
 saved contribute to the loss, and gave as a reason that the doctrine 
 of avaries communes is confined to the maritime law. (Paris, 17 
 janv. 1862, D. 1862. 2. 30.) MM. Lyon-Caen et Renault 
 approve of the decision, but not upon this ground. 
 
 They say the saving of the 28,000 francs was not due here to 
 the sacrifice of the other bags, but to the ignorance of the robbers. 
 It was by cas fortuit that the money was saved. (Traite de Droit 
 Commercial, 6, n. 871.) 
 
 This seems too refined. If the driver had not given up the 
 bags which the robbers could see, they would have ransacked the 
 eoacli and discovered the other bags. 
 
 I prefer the view that the decision was wrong. It was a true 
 example of avarie commune, and the court has power to apply the 
 principle to cases which happen on land, though, naturally, the 
 maritime cases are more common. 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence. 
 
 The Egyptian jurisprudence in regard to the action de in rem 
 verso is meagre, and sometimes the courts apply the name action 
 de in rem verso to mean the action resulting from gestion 
 d'affaires. (C. A. Alex. 21 dec. 1892, B. L. J. V, 85.) 
 
 The following are illustrations of the action de in rem verso 
 in the sense which is used in the French jurisprudence: — 
 
 Where there is a secret partnership, or, as it is called, an asso- 
 ciation en participation, the partnership has no personality, and 
 third parties who contract with a partner have no action against 
 any one of the other partners except upon the principle de in rem 
 verso, and to the extent of the benefit which he has received. 
 (C. A. Alex. 19 fevr. 1903, B. L. J. XV, 157; C. A. Alex. 17 
 mai 1900, B. L. J. XII, 253. As to the character of association 
 en participation, see Lyon-Caen et Renault, Manuel de Droit 
 Commercial, 11th ed. n. 325.) 
 
 The purchaser of an immoveable who has been evicted can claim 
 from the owner, by the action de in rem verso, reimbursement of 
 his outlays necessary or beneficial, to the extent which they benefit 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 175 
 
 the owner. (C. A. Alex. 16 mars 1899, B. L. J. XI, 162. Cf. 
 C. A. Alex. 13 fevr. 1895, B. L. J. VII, 122.) 
 
 The following cases also illustrate the rule: — The Administra- 
 tion of Ports and Lighthouses made use without consent of a plan 
 of the harbour of Alexandria made by one of their engineers, but 
 made unofficially and in his leisure hours. It was held that the 
 Egyptian Government was liable to him to the extent of the 
 benefit. (C. A. Alex. 26 mai 1910, B. L. J. XXII, 337.) 
 
 A clandestine pipe was placed in a house in such a manner as to 
 carry water from the pipe of the water-company without affecting 
 their meter. The pipe performed this service for a number of 
 years before it was discovered. The defendant, who occupied 
 the house with his family, was prosecuted at the instance of the 
 water-company for stealing the water, but acquitted for want of 
 proof of his knowledge of the position of the pipe. In a civil 
 action, however, he was held liable to pay L. E. 20 for the water 
 which he had consumed in good faith to the detriment of the 
 company. (C. A. Alex. 21 mars 1900, B. L. J. XII, 170.) 
 
 Attempt to determine the principles governing the matter. 
 
 It being admitted that there are many cases in which one person 
 is benefited by the action of another, without being thereby placed 
 under a legal duty to pay for the benefit, while there are, on the 
 other hand, certain cases in which the person 'is bound to pay, is 
 it possible to find a criterion to distinguish the one class of cases 
 from the other? 
 
 Some of the French writers who enjoy the highest reputation 
 explain the action de in rem v&rsQjis a kind of abnormal gestion 
 d'affaires. It is available in such a case, for example, as when a 
 man, acting in his own interest, and not intending to benefit 
 another, does, nevertheless, confer a benefit upon this other. 
 fraction de in rem verso, quoique se trouvant en dehors des con- 
 ditions du quasi-contrat de gestion d'affaires, nen doit pas moins 
 pourtant etre considSree comwie une action en quelque sorte auxili- 
 aire de V action negotiorum gestorum, lorsque, par une circonstance 
 quelconque, le fait juridique, qui s'est 'produit, ne reunit pas toutes 
 les conditions requises pour constituer le quasi-contrat de gestion 
 d'affaires. Tel a tou jours ete, en effet, son caractere, dapres les 
 traditions les plus andennes ; et cest la, certes, un argument con- 
 siderable dans un sujet qui est entre, tout entier, dans nos lois 
 modernes avec le cortege des regies romaines. (Demolombe, 31, 
 n. 49.) 
 
176 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Liiuiviit is to the same effect: La jurisprudence confond, en 
 gefZeral, V action de in rem verso avec Vacticm de gestion d'affaires ; 
 ccld n'est pas juridique en un sens, puisque les deux actions dif- 
 ferent ; mats la confusion s'expiique t en ce sens que les deux actions 
 procedent de la meme cause, \et qiielles ne different que quant a 
 I'etiemdm dies obligations du maitre. (Laurent, 20, no. 338. 
 Cf . Larombiere, art. 1375, n. 14.) 
 
 But if this is the explanation, why is it that the conditions of 
 the two actions are not the same? Why is it that, when the action 
 is upon gestion d'affaires, the gestor can claim reinbursement for 
 his outlays if they were beneficial at the time they were made, 
 whereas, when the action is de in rem verso, the plaintiff can claim 
 only for the benefit existing at the date of the action, or, at any 
 rate, for a profit which the other party has actually received and 
 enjoyed? Is not the essence of gestion d'affaires a voluntary 
 interference for the benefit of another in cases of urgency, whereas, 
 in many of the cases of de in rem verso these elements are entirely 
 lacking? 
 
 Most French authorities now agree that this explanation, at 
 any rate, must be rejected. (Loubers, in Rev. Crit. 1912, p. 400; 
 Ripert and Teisseire, in Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 741; Bartin, in 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th fed. 9, p. 355, note 9.) 
 
 In fact it would be much truer to say that, instead of the action 
 de in rem verso being a special and abnormal case of gestion 
 d'affaires, gestion d'affaires itself is a special application of the 
 broad rule that a man is not allowed to enrich himself at the 
 expense of another. (See M. Planiol's note to Req. 16 juill. 
 1890, D. 1891. 1. 49. Cf. Cass. 18 mai 1873, D. 1874. 1. 269.) 
 
 Confusion between action de in rem verso and action on 
 gestion d'affaires. 
 
 In some of the French cases there is an absolute confusion 
 between the action de in rem verso and the action by the negotio- 
 rum gestor. Thus, in one arret of the Cour de Cassation, we read 
 les obligations reciproques qui peuvent resulter d'un quasi-con- 
 trat de gestion d'affaires naissent du fait meme de la gestion et 
 de la loi, et non de Vintention des parties; il importe pen que 
 celui qui a fait Vacte de gestion ait entendu agir tout a la fois 
 dams son interet personnel, et dans V interet d'un tiers, si en realite 
 ce tier* etait interesse a facte de gestion et en a profile. (Cass. 
 18 juin 1872, D. 72. 1. 471.) 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 177 
 
 And, in another arret, the Cow de Cassation said: quand un 
 
 tiers fait vn aMe dont profile un proprietaire, il_gere reellement, 
 quoiquc inroloi/hi/remeut, et a son insu, V affaire de ce proprie- 
 taire. (Cass. 10 juill. 1890, S. 94. 1. 19, 1). 91. 1. 49, and 
 the note of M. Planiol, who draws attention to the confusion. 
 See, for other illustrations in the administrative law of the same 
 confusion, Eipert et Teisseire, in Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 736.) 
 
 But, by definition, there is not any gestion d'affaires, in the 
 proper sense of the term, unless there is an intentional interference 
 in the business of another, or, as the Egyptian Code expresses it 
 still more clearly, unless it is the act of one person intentionally 
 iprocuring a benefit for another. (C. C. F. 1372; C. C. E. 
 144/205.) 
 
 The person who interferes in this way is, in a sense, specially 
 favoured by the law, because he can recover what he has spent if 
 it was expended beneficially at the time, although owing to some 
 fortuitous event, the benefit may have disappeared before the date 
 of action. The right of the plaintiff in the action de in rem verso 
 is more limited, as will be explained later, and it is absolutely 
 necessarv to keep the two actions entirely distinct. 
 
 Theory that source of obligation is delictual. 
 
 Another explanation is that of Planiol, that the cause of the 
 obligation to reimburse is delictual. The person benefited has not 
 received the benefit by a fait illicite done by him, but it would be 
 a fait illicite on his part to retain the benefit without paying for 
 it. Planiol, 2, n. 812, and n. 937.) M. Ernest Vergniaud in 
 his excellent monograph accepts the theory of M. Planiol. (L'en- 
 richissement sans cause, p. 162.) 
 
 But this explanation also appears to be very forced. In many 
 cases the parson benefited has remained entirely passive. 
 
 There is no act of his which we can regard as fault. To say 
 that he commits an unlawful act if he retains the benefit without 
 paying for it is a statement equivalent merely to saying that the 
 law obliges him to pay for the benefit. It does not afford any 
 reason. We might with equal truth say that the debtor in a 
 contractual obligation commits an unlawful act if he does not pay 
 his debt. But, just as in this case, it is the contract which gene- 
 rates the obligation, so in the case of enrichment, we must look 
 for some legal reason which makes it unlawful for the defendant 
 to retain it without paying for it. The explanation of M. Planiol 
 
 W.— VOL. II. 12 
 
17S THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 explains nothing as to this. And if in spite of these arguments, 
 we are to regard the defendant's obligation as delictual, why are 
 we not to follow the ordinary rule, and make the offender liable 
 for all the loss suffered by the plaintiff? 
 
 Why is the measure of the offender's liability to be the "amount 
 of the enrichment? (See Ripert et Teisseire, p. 758; Bartin, 
 in Auln\ el Ivan, -3th cd. 9, p. 355, note 9/) 
 
 One cannot but feel as to M. Planiol's theory, that the eminent 
 writer is carried away by his desire of simplification. Nothing 
 is gained by extending the traditional theory of the nature and 
 consequences of ;i wrong. A fait iUicite renders the wrong-doer 
 responsible for all the damages directly caused thereby to another. 
 But, in this case, even if, by a stretch of language, we were to 
 call the person enriched a wrong-doer, it is manifest that the 
 damage suffered by the person who has procured the enrichment 
 was caused to himself by his own act and not by any act of the. 
 other. 
 
 Theory that source of obligation is the creation of value. 
 
 A still bolder attempt to place the action de in rem verso upon 
 a new foundation is that made by MM. Ripert et Teisseire. 
 JEssai d'une theorie de V ' enrichissement sans cause en droit civil 
 francais, Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 727.) 
 
 These writers, after criticising with much force the theory 
 that the rule against unjust enrichment can he regarded either as 
 an abnormal case of negotiorum gestio, or as being founded upon 
 quasi-delict, proceed to give a theory of their own which may be 
 thus summarised. The traditional theory that responsibility is 
 based upon fault must, they say, be abandoned in favour of the 
 theoiy of objective responsibility, namely, that the person, who 
 for his profit has created a risk, must pay for the damages caused 
 by his act, whether there was fault in the traditional sense or not. 
 (This subject belongs to the law of Responsibility.) 
 
 Accepting the new doctrine of the risque cree, these writers 
 say there must be a corresponding theory of profit cree : La 
 notion d'une responsabilite da simple fait repose tout entiere suf 
 cette idee qu'il est juste, quit est bon, de faire supporter a chaque 
 act i rite les dommages qu'elle cause. Les memes raisons, les memes 
 considerations doirrnt faire trouver bon et juste que chaque activite 
 puisse revendiquer pour elle les resultats utiles qui sont son muvre. 
 Cette deuxieme proposition est t'exacte contrepartie de la pre- 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VEKSO. 179 
 
 miere, elle en est le complement necessaire, et torn les raisonne- 
 ments que Von pent faire valoir a Vappui de Vune doivent pouvoir 
 servir a la justification de V autre. 
 
 Qui n. ctjl Ip risque, dit-ou. doit le supporter. Qui a cree le 
 profit, doit en beneficier. SHI y a line theorie du risque cree, il 
 faut qu'il y ait une theorie correspondante du profit cree. (Rev. 
 Trim. 1904, p. 756.) 
 
 But in spite of the ingenuity with which this theory is pre- 
 sented by its authors, it must be rejected without hesitation. 
 
 The theory of objective responsibility has not been accepted 
 as a general principle of the French law and has, certainly, no 
 place in the Egyptian law. 
 
 Moreover, if the theory of MM. Ripert et Teisseire were to be 
 accepted, it would lead to results inconsistent . with the jurispru- 
 dence. If the sufficient basis of the plaintiff's claim were, merely, 
 that he had by his act procured an enrichment, it would be im- 
 material whether he had done so without suffering any prejudice 
 himself, or whether the enrichment had ceased to exist at the 
 date of the action. 
 
 According to the French jurisprudence, on the other hand, the 
 plaintiff has no right unless he has suffered a prejudice, and his 
 claim is limited to the enrichment subsisting at the date of the 
 .action, or, at any rate, to an enrichment of which the defendant 
 has reaped the benefit. (Cass. 18 oct. 1904, D. 1905. 1. 119;, 
 Lyon, 11 janv. 1906, D. 1906. 2. 132; Loubers, Rev. Crit. 1912, 
 p. 413, and p. 474: Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 363. 
 
 Conditions of the action de in rem verso as determined by 
 the French jurisprudence. 
 
 The action de in rem verso is not available unless four condi- 
 tions are fulfilled: — 
 
 (1) The defendant must have been enriched; 
 
 (2) This enrichment must have been directly caused by a pre- 
 judice suffered by the plaintiff; 
 
 (3) The enrichment must have been unjust, or, as it is other- 
 wise expressed, the defendant must not have a just cause for 
 retaining the benefit without payment. 
 
 (4) The enrichment must be still existing at the date of the 
 action, or, at any rate, the defendant must have reaped the full 
 benefit of it. (B.-L. et Barde, 3rd ed. 4, n. 2849. XVI; Colin 
 
 12 (2) 
 

 180 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 et Capitant, 2, p. 406. Cf . Ripert ct Teisseire, Rev. Trim. 1904 r 
 }). 727 ; Loubers, Rev. Crit. 1912, p. 396; note by Xaquet to Cass. 
 23 now 1908, S. 1910. 1. 425; Solus, H., L' Action Directe, these, 
 Paris, 1914, p. 242; Bouche-Le Clerc, L' Action de in rem verso 
 en droit prive, these, Paris, 1913.) 
 
 These conditions require some explanation. 
 
 (1) The enrichment. 
 
 It must appear that the patrimony of the defendant has been 
 increased by money or by money's worth. It is not enough, in 
 all cases, that money has passed to the defendant, for this may 
 not have enriched him. If, for instance, money has been paid 
 to a lunatic, and he has, thereupon, thrown it into the Nile, there 
 is no enrichment of his patrimony. (See Cass. 2 janv. 1901, 
 S. 1901. 1. 192; Demolombe, 29, n. 172.) 
 
 The following is an example of a case which failed for want 
 of proof of enrichment. 
 
 A company which operated a railway between Aries and Pont- 
 vieille, had a contract with the city of Aries by which the city 
 granted it a subvention. This contract was annulled, and the 
 company sued the city of Aries by the action de in rem verso. 
 
 The claim was rejected because there had not been any trans- 
 mission de valeur. The property of the city had not been en- 
 riched, although the inhabitants had derived an advantage from 
 the existence of the railway. (Cass. 31 juill. 1895, S. 96. 1. 397, 
 D. 95. 1. 391.) 
 
 This case has sometimes been misunderstood as laying down 
 a rule that there must in every case be a material transmission of 
 /^value from the plaintiff to the defendant. The claim will lie for 
 personal services rendered by the plaintiff, for example, services 
 of a domestic kind, just as much as for reimbursement of actual 
 money spent. (Poitiers, 2 dec. 1907, D. 1908. 2. 332.) It is 
 enough that there is I'existence d'un (wantage qu'il aurait, par 
 un sacrifice ou un fait personnel, procure a celui contre lequel il 
 agit. (Cass. 15 juin 1892, S. 93. 1. 281, D. 92. 1. 596; Loubers, 
 Rev. Crit. 1912, p. 472.) 
 
 Nay more, there may have been an actual transmission de 
 valeur from one patrimony to another, and, yet, the court may 
 hold that there has been no enrichment. 
 
 The court of Amiens refused to consider a partnership as en- 
 riched by a sum of 100,000 francs, which had been lent to one of 
 the partners in his own name, because, although the society had 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 181 
 
 benefited by the loan, the partner was a debtor bo the firm after 
 making allowance for the sum by which it had profited. (Amiens, 
 16 fevr. 1901, sous Cass. 26 janv. 1903, D. 1904. 1. 391. CI'. 
 Paris, 21 fevr. 1905, smts Cass. 9 et 10 nov. 1909, D. 1911. 1. 
 169.) 
 
 (2) The enrichment must be a direct consequence of the' 
 prejudice suffered by the plaintiff. 
 
 The rule has been thus formulated by the Cow de Cassation: 
 pour que Taction d)e in rem verso soit recevable, il ne suffit pas 
 que le defendeur ait recueilli un advantage prenant sa source dans 
 un acte du demandeur, il faut que cet uvautage result e d'une 
 depense faite par le second dans Vinteret du premier. Cass. 
 18 oct. 1904, D. 1905. 1. 119.) 
 
 It is the application of this rule which excludes the claim when 
 the plaintiff acted in his own interest, and involuntarily shared 
 the benefit with the defendant. This is so when, for example, 
 the plaintiff has improved his immoveable, or has brought about 
 the suppression of a nuisance, and has thus indirectly benefited 
 his neighbours as well as himself. (Loubers, in Revue Critique, 
 1912, p. 412. See Cass. 31 juill. 1895, S. 96. 1. 397. 
 
 In some of the cases in which the rule has been applied, there 
 has been in addition another reason for rejecting 1 the claim, namely, 
 that the plaintiff has been guilty of negligence, and that the loss 
 was caused by his own fault. This was so in the case mentioned 
 above, where the credit -fonder paid off a hypothec without taking 
 the precaution of obtaining subrogation. (Req. 11 juill. 1889, 
 S.90. 1. 97, supra, y. 171.) 
 
 The prejudice suffered by the plaintiff is one measure of his 
 claim. He can never recover more than enough to make up for his 
 loss, and he cannot recover always even so much as this, because 
 part of the benefit may be no longer subsisting at the date of the 
 action. (Lyon, 11 janv. 1906, sous Cass. 18 oct. 1904, S. 1907. 
 
 1. 465. Cf. Paris, ler dec. 1910, Gaz. Trib. 1911. 2. 165, 
 D. 1911. 5. 1; Rev. Trim. 1911, p. 434; Aubiy et Ran, 4th ed. 
 6, p. 246; Loubers, Rev. Crit. 1912, p. 479; Colin et Capitant, 
 
 2, p. 409.) 
 
 The enrichment of the defendant must be the consequence of 
 the impoverishment of the plaintiff. It ,is universally agreed that 
 there must be a connexity between the enrichment of the one and 
 the impoverishment of the other, but some authors deny that 
 there must be a relation of cause and effect between them. (See 
 
182 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Labbe, note to Req. 11 juill. 1889, S. 90. 1. 97; Vergniaud, E., 
 L'Enriehissement sans cause, p. 201.) 
 
 M. Bartin prefers to say that, in order to succeed in his claim, 
 the plaintiff must prove an indivisibility of origin between the 
 enrichment of the defendant and his own impoverishment. They 
 are two aspects of the same fact . (Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 9, p . 358,. 
 note 9, septies.) 
 
 (3) The defendant must not have a just cause for retaining 
 the enrichment without payment. 
 
 This is the most difficult point, and the one upon which there 
 is the greatest controversy. 
 
 When is the defendant in a position to say, " I have a just cause 
 for keeping the enrichment"? 
 
 (a; Animus donandi. 
 
 In some cases this defence is easy . If he can show, for example, 
 that the benefit he received from the plaintiff was intended as a 
 gift, he will not have to pay for it because the plaintiff has after- 
 wards changed his mind. (Of. C. A. Alex. 24 dec. 1902, B. L. 
 J. XV, 75.) 
 
 But the proof in such cases of the plaintiff's state of mind may 
 be difficult. This question arises not infrequently in cases where 
 the claim is for domestic sendees. If a grown-up son has been 
 in the habit of doing certain work for his father, or if a sister has 
 kept her brother's house and saved him the expense of a house- 
 keeper, it may be evident that the defendant has reaped a pecuniary 
 advantage. 
 
 But if the understanding of the parties was that these services 
 were rendered out of affection, and with no idea of making a 
 pecuniary claim', the action will not lie. And in such a case where 
 the services are rendered by one member of the family to another 
 residing in the same household, the presumption will be that they 
 were meant to be gratuitous. (See Domat, Lois Civiles, liv. 11. 
 titr. IV. s. 2, nos. 9 and 10; Trib. de Paix de Lille, 1895, D. 
 1897. 2. 187; Ripert et Teisseire, Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 793; and 
 compare many interesting American cases collected in Keener, 
 Quasi-Contracts, p. 315 scq.) 
 
 (b) Contractual right to take benefit. 
 
 A lessee makes repairs upon the house let of the kind which by 
 the French law he was bound to make. The lessee does not pay 
 for them. The contractor who has made the repairs cannot claim 
 
ACTIO DE IN REM VERSO. 183 
 
 from the owner of tin; house the plus-value given to it 1>\ tie 
 repairs, for the lessor gets nothing to which he was not entitled. 
 (C. C. E. 370/453; C. C. E. 378/463; Paris, 26 juin 1899. 
 S. 1901. 2. 167; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2849, XXIV. Contrast 
 such a case as Iieq. 16 juill. 1890, D. 91. 1. 49, where the owner 
 got constructions to which he was not entitled.) 
 
 So witli other contracts. If the defendant can show that be 
 has a right by contract to take the benefit, it will be the contraot 
 which will determine whether he has any correlative duty to paj . 
 The same principle applies when the claim is against a third party 
 who is enriched as an indirect consequence of the performance of 
 a contract to which he was not a party. 
 
 A farmer who farms another's land in virtue of a lease, employs 
 labourers for the harvest . They have no action against the owner 
 of the farm for their wages. On ne peut consider er le pro- 
 prietaire qui a regu le prix du fermage ou set part de la recolte 
 conformement aux stipulations du bail, commie s'etant, sans cause 
 legitime, enriohi au detriment de I'ouurier. (Cass. 18 oct. 1898, 
 S. 99. 1. 165, D. 99. 1. 105.) 
 
 And, in general, when the person enriched, received the benefit 
 in payment of a contract with him, the third party who has 
 indirectly procured the enrichment has no action de in rem verso. 
 There is no direct relation between the person who is prejudiced 
 and the person who is enriched. (See Cass. 8 fevr. 1909, S. 
 1911. 1. 313, and note of M. Bourcart.) 
 
 The case which has been above referred to, where the claim was 
 by a man who had supplied manure for a crop which the owner 
 of the land had reaped, has been much debated. By some writers 
 it has been interpreted as affirming the proposition that, when 
 there has been a transmission of value from the plaintiff to the 
 property of the defendant, the action de in rem verso is admis- 
 sible. But this proposition is too wide and its application would 
 lead to results which are inequitable. If it were sound, any person 
 who had done work which had increased the value of premises in 
 the hands of a lessee would have two rights of action, an action 
 on the contract against the lessee, and an action on the quasi- 
 contract against the lessor. And he would enjoy the benefit of 
 the second action although the lessee had failed to pay his rent, 
 or, otherwise, to fulfil his contract with the lessor. 
 
 There is no reason why, in this case as in others, the creditor 
 
184 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 who has relied upon the credit of his debtor should not take the 
 risk of his debtor's insolvency. 
 
 In the rase of the supplier of the manure there were special 
 circumstances. The owner of the land had no right to the crop, 
 bill when the lease was resiliated the crop was abandoned to him 
 in part-payment of the rent. A value was put on the crop sur- 
 rendered in this way, and from this value was deducted the price 
 of the manure. The owner of the land had, in effect, taken the 
 crop upon condition that he should pay for the manure. The 
 ease must accordingly be considered as a decision d'espece, and 
 not as laying down any general principle. (Cass. 15 juin 1892, 
 S. 93. 1. 281, D. 92. 1. 596; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 360;, 
 Ripert et Teisseire, in Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 795. Contrast, Req. 
 23 nov. 1908, S. 1910. 1. 425, and, specially, the criticism of 
 M. Naquet at the foot of p. 426, col. 2.) 
 
 (4) The enrichment must be subsisting. 
 
 It is the generally accepted view that the action de in rem verso, 
 being a kind of action for restitution, the defendant can never 
 have to pay more than the amount by which he is enriched at the 
 date of the action . 
 
 We have seen in explaining the law of negotiorum gestio, that 
 the measure of the gestor's claim is the benefit he conferred at 
 the time when he incurred the expense. If the gestor had repaired 
 a roof, his claim against the owner of the house would not be 
 destroyed by the fact that the house had been burnt down directly 
 afterwards by a fortuitous event, and that, in consequence, the 
 benefit which he had conferred upon its owner had been lost. 
 
 But when the conditions of negotiorum gestio are not present, 
 and the claim is under the action de in rem verso, the subsequent 
 loss of the benefit would be fatal. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, 
 n. 2849, XXVI; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 6, p. 247; 5th ed. 9, 
 p. 363; Lyon, 11 janv. 1906, D. 1906. 2. 132; D. Swpp. Oblig. 
 n. 2287: Laurent, 20, n. 340; D. X. C. C. art. 1375, n. 79. 
 Contra. Ripert et Teisseire, Rev. Trim. 1904, p. 787.) 
 
 Bui in saying that the defendant cannot be liable for more than 
 his enrichment at the date of the action, it is not intended to 
 exclude his liability to pay for services rendered to him of which 
 he has received the full advantage. If the plaintiff has rendered 
 domestic or professional services to the defendant, and these were 
 
ACTIO DE IN KKM VERSO. 185 
 
 not intended to be gratuitous, the defendant's liability will not be 
 excluded by the fact that the services had been completed before 
 the date of the action. (Poitiers, 2 dec. 1907, D. 1908. 2. 332.) 
 
 The action de in rem verso is a subsidiary action. 
 
 The action de in rem vei'so is an equitable remedy which is not 
 available when the plaintiff has another remedy at his disposal. 
 If he has a remedy by way of an action on contract, he is tied 
 up to this remedy. (Cass. 8 fevr. 1909, S. 1911. 1. 313, and 
 note of M. Bourcart; Loubers, in Rev. Crit. 1912, p. 482.) 
 
 The remedy is available only when the plaintiff has no other 
 right of action to obtain the restitution or its value either against 
 the person benefited or against the third party, based either upon 
 contract, quasi-contract, delict or quasi-delict. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 9, p. 361.) 
 
 Comparison with other laws. 
 
 The principle underlying the action de in rem verso has been 
 formulated in several of the more recent codes. Under the Ger- 
 man Code, Quioonque, par prestation faite par une autre per- 
 sonne ou de toute autre maniere, fait une acquisition sans cause 
 juridique aux depens de cette autre personne, est oblige vis-a-vis 
 d'elle a restitution. Cette obligation existe egalement lorsque la 
 cause juridique disparait ulterieuremxmt cm que le resultat pour- 
 suivi au moyen d'une prestation, tel qu'il ressort du contenu de 
 facte juridique, ne se realise pas. 
 
 Est egalement consideree comme prestation la reconnaissance 
 contractuelle de Vexistence ou de la non-existence d'un rapport 
 d'' 'obligation (art. 812, where see note by M. Saleillas). 
 
 The Swiss Code says, Celui qui, sans cause legitime, s'est 
 enrichi aux depens d'autrui, est tenu a restitution. 
 
 La restitution est due, em particulier, de ce qui a ete recu sans 
 cause valable, en vertu d'une cause qui ne s'est pas realisee ou 
 d'une cause qui a cesse d'exister. 
 
 (Code Fed. Oblig. art. 62.) 
 
 And the Morocco Code of Obligations which does not contain 
 any special articles upon gestion d'affaires has the following 
 articles: — 
 
 Art. 66. — Celui qui a recu ou se trouve pmseder wne chose, 
 
186 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ou autre wleur appurtenant a autrui, sans une cause qui justifie 
 oet enrichiss&ment, est tenu die la restituer a celui au depens duquel 
 il s'est enridhi. 
 
 Art. til— Celui qui, de bonne foi, a retfce un profit du 
 travail ou de la chose d'autirui, sans une cause qui justifie ce profit, 
 est tenu d'indemniser celui aux depens duquel il s'est enrichi dans 
 la me sure oil il a profile de son fait mi de sa chose. 
 
 (For the English law, see infra, p. 197.) 
 
QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 187 
 
 C 
 
 I JulU- 
 
 j^n^*- 
 
 CHAPTER IX. 
 
 THE QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT 
 
 NOT DUE. 
 
 The Egyptian codes deal with this matter in lour articles. lie 
 who receives that which is not due to him is bound to restore it. 
 If he received in bad faith, hie is liable for loss, interest and fruits. 
 Nevertheless, if a payment is voluntarily made in discharge of an 
 obligation, restitution is not due even where such obligation is not 
 enforceable by law. 
 
 Restitution is not due, if one person has by mistake paid the 
 debt of another to the creditor of such other person, provided that 
 such creditor acts in good faith, and thai the document of tith 
 has been destroyed ; but this provision is without prejudice to the 
 right of recourse which the person who has paid the debt has 
 against the real debtor. (C. C. N. 145—148; C. C. M. 205— 
 209.) 
 
 These articles reproduce with slight modifications those of the 
 French Code, omitting however three articles which state rules 
 consequential on those previously given. 
 
 Except in one. or two points of detail, which will be noticed, 
 there is no doubt the Egyptian legislator intends to preserve the 
 French law on the subject. (C. C. F. 1376-1381; C. C. Q. 
 1047-1052..) 
 
 The codes state the conditions attaching to the action called 
 in the French law the action en repetition de Hindu, which is 
 sometimes denoted also by its Roman name conflict io indebiti. 
 
 If there is no debt to extinguish, the payment has been made 
 without a cause, unless the intention was to make a gift? and a 
 payment made without a cause can be recovered. Such a payment 
 is said to have been made indument. It may be that the debt never 
 existed, or it may be that it existed at one time, but has subse- 
 quently ceased to exist. 
 
 If the payment has been made by a mandatary, the action of 
 
188 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 repetition may be brought either by him or by the person for 
 whom he made the payment. (Req. 24 avril 1907, D. 1907. 1. 
 502.) 
 
 Repetition when there was no error. 
 
 In three oases proof of error is not required: — 
 
 (1) The first case is that in which by the Roman law the action 
 •condictio causa data causa non secuta was available. (Girard, 
 Manuel, 5th ed. p. 622.) 
 
 The payment is made in view of some future consideration 
 which has not been realised. It is. in fact, a conditional 
 payment, and the condition, not having been fulfilled, there is an 
 action for its recovery. For example, a relative of one of the 
 spouses has paid a dowry before the marriage, or made a donation 
 to one of the spouses in the marriage-contract, and the marriage 
 fails to oome off; the money paid can be recovered. (C. C. F. 
 1088; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2839; B.-L. Le Courtois et SurviUe, 
 Contrat de manage, 1, n. 196.) 
 
 In oases of this kind there is no necessity to prove error on the 
 part of the person making the payment. The basis of the action 
 is not a payment in mistake. It is a payment made in view of a 
 future cause which has not been realised. 
 
 (2) The same principle applies when the contract under which 
 the payment was made has been annulled. If the buyer has paid 
 the price and the contract of sale is annulled, he has a right to 
 repetition of the price. For instance, a house which is hypo- 
 thecated is seized and sold by creditors. The purchaser pays the 
 money to the hypothecary creditor, and he is subsequently evicted 
 from the property by a third party who turns out to be the true 
 owner. The purchaser can recover the price from the creditor 1 
 whom he has paid. The sale to him turns out to have been null, . 
 therefore he paid what was not due. (Planiol, 2, n. 844; Cass. 
 28 dec. 1885, D. 86. 1. 433; D. N. C. C. art. 1376, n. 64; 
 C. A. Alex. 23 nov. 1899, B. L. J. XII, 27. Cf. C. A. Alex. 
 17 janv. 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 92.) 
 
 (3) Does the same principle apply when the payment was made 
 in discharge of an unlawful or immoral contract? Here, too, 
 it is not a question of error, but simply of money paid for an 
 unlawful cause. The action Avas called in this case in the Roman 
 law condictio oh fur pern causam. (Girard. Manuel, 5th- ed. 
 p. 622.) ' 
 
QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 18i> 
 
 The question whether repetition is allowable in this case has- 
 been discussed earlier in speaking- of the nature of cause. {Supra, 
 I, p. 175.) 
 
 Payment made in error. 
 
 The articles upon repetition in the Egyptian Code and those in 
 the French Code upon which they are based, are probably not 
 intended to deal with the case where money has been paid for a 
 consideration which has failed, or for an unlawful cause. In the 
 former of these cases the right to repetition undoubtedly exists, 
 but it can be founded upon other provisions of the code and 
 specially upon that which says that an obligation must have a 
 lawful cause. (Cf. C. C. E. 94/148; C. C. F. 1131; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 4, n. 2837; D. N. C. C. art. 1376, n. 1-55. See, however, 
 Colin et Capitant, 2. p. 400.) 
 
 The articles under consideration have in view the payment 
 made in error where the error is the only cause of the payment. 
 There is a complete absence of any obligation between the person 
 paying who is commonly called the solvens, and the person who 
 receives the payment who is known as the accipiens. The action 
 is available only to the person who has made the payment or to 
 his assignees or persons subrogated to him. (Cass. 17 nov. 1914, 
 D. 1917. 1. 61. The error may take one of three forms: 
 
 (1) There never was airy obligation between the parties. The 
 person who paid did not owe anything, and there was nothing due 
 to the person who received the payment. For example, a wife, 
 as heir of her husband, pays a bill which she believes to be signed 
 by him, whereas the signature is a forgery. (Cass. 19 janv. 
 1886, D. 86. 1. 88.) A person pays a tax which he does not owe, 
 because the tax was not imposed according to the law. (Req. 
 10 nov. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 392; Req. 2 juill. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 
 175.) 
 
 (2) There is a debt, but the debtor pays it to a person who- 
 is not the creditor. 
 
 (3) There is a debt, and it is paid to the creditor but by a 
 person other than the debtor. (B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2833.) 
 
 And, in this last case, we must remember that the law permits 
 one man to pay the debt of another, and that if he does so 
 voluntarily — en connaissance de cause— he has no right to repeti- 
 tion. It is only when he is under the mistaken impression that 
 he is paying his own debt that this right exisl>. C. A. Alex. 
 
190 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 20 jum 1895, B. L. J. VII, 351; C. A. Alex. 20 avril 1911, 
 
 B. L. J. XXIII, 274.; 
 
 1 1 is not necessary that the accipiens should be in error but it 
 is nece ssary that the solvens should be so. If the accipiens knew 
 he was receiving what was not due to him, his bad faith will 
 cause him to be more severely dealt with. The error of the solvens 
 <loes not need to be an error of fact, it may equally be an error 
 of law. So, if a man pays an illegal tax, believing that he is 
 legally bound to pay it, he pays in error and has a right to repeti- 
 tion/ (Beq. 10 nov. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 392; Req. 21 juiU. 
 1908, D. 1909. 1. 175; C. A. Alex. 7 mai 1908, B. L. J. 
 XX, 202; C. A. Alex. 20 fevr. 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 187.) 
 
 In such a case, it is not necessary to prove that the payment 
 was made under compulsion or violence morale. 
 
 Destruction of the title. 
 
 There is one case where a payment in error cannot be repeated 
 from the payee. This is the case which is thus stated in the 
 Egyptian Native Code: Restitution is not due if one person 
 has hy mistake paid the debt of another to the creditor of such 
 other person, provided that such creditor acts in good faith, and 
 that the document of £Ule has been destroyed; but this provision 
 is without prejudice to the right of recourse which the person who 
 has paid the debt has against the real debtor. (C. C. N. 148; 
 
 C. C. M. 209/, The article is based on the French Code. 
 (C. C. F. 1377.') 
 
 A man who believes himself to owe a certain debt, although 
 this is an error on his part, pays the debt to the creditor. 
 
 The creditor, receiving- the payment in good faith, and think- 
 ing that his title or document of debt is now unnecessary, destroys 
 the title. If the debtor who had paid by mistake could recover 
 from the creditor what he had paid, when he had discovered his 
 error, the creditor would be in a helpless position. He would 
 have no title by which to establish his claim against the real 
 debtor. Accordingly, the law says that he may keep the money, 
 and the man who has paid the other's debt by mistake will be 
 left with his recourse against the real debtor. This is in fact 
 an illustration of a general principle that when the law has to 
 choose which of two innocent parties is to suffer a loss, if there 
 has been any negligence on the part of one of them, it is this 
 one who is made the victim. 
 
^QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. l!)l 
 
 The creditor who got what was due to him in good faith has 
 committed no fault however slight. But the person who paid 
 ought to have made sure that he owed the debt. It is generally 
 held in France that the words supprime son litre ought not to be 
 strictly construed, and that the same principle should apply to 
 the case where the creditor in consequence of the payment lias 
 released a security or has allowed the debt to prescribe. 
 
 For here, also, if he had to restore the money, he would be 
 helpless and exposed to the risk of losing his money by no fault 
 of his own. (B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2836; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 
 4, p. 733; D. N. C. C. art. 1376, n. 262; Caen, 20 mars 1891, 
 D. 92. 2. 177, and the note; Cass. 27 nov. 1912, D. 1913. 1. 
 96.) 
 
 The same considerations would apply to the expression in the 
 Egyptian Code: the doeument of title has been destroyed. 
 (C.*C.N. 148.) 
 
 But the point is not very clear, because it is a general rule of 
 construction that exceptions are not^to be extended by analogy. 
 (Eeq. 4 aout 1895, D. 95. 1. 362; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2836.) 
 The Code of Quebec removes the doubt b}' saying that there is no 
 right to repetition "when the title has in good faith been can- 
 celled or has become ineffective in consequence of the payment. - ' 
 (C. C. Q. 1048.) 
 
 Onus of proof. 
 
 The principal difficulties in questions of repetition are in regard 
 to the onus of proof. The plaintiff, according to general prin- 
 ciples, must prove all the facts necessary to support his claim. 
 Now there are three essential conditions applying to the action 
 of repetition in the oases dealt with here in the code: 
 
 (1) A payment. 
 
 (2) No debt. 
 
 (3) An error. 
 
 It falls upon the plaintiff to prove these three facts. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, 3rd ed. 4, n. 2832; Dail. Supp. vo. Oblig. n. 2324; 
 Cass. 25 nov. 1901, D. 1903. 1. 549.) 
 
 But in regard to the manner of proof and to the presumptions 
 of fact which may exist in certain cases there is a considerable 
 difference of opinion. It will be best to take the three facts 
 in order. 
 
192 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. % 
 
 (1) Payment. 
 
 The plaintiff must prove the payment according to the ordinary 
 rules of evidence, that is to say, by writing unless the cases fall 
 within one of the exceptions given in the code. (C. C. E. 215 ; — 
 222/380 — 387.) It is not enough to say that seeing that the 
 obligation arises from quasi-contract, the proof can be made by 
 parole. 
 
 A person who makes a payment can easily obtain a receipt for 
 it, and it is reasonable to expect him to do so. It is only in one 
 of the oases stated in the code, or where there is a commencement 
 of proof in writing, that parole proof of the payment is admissible. 
 (Laurent, 20, n. 366; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2625; Hue, 
 8, n. 296; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 245; D. N. C. C. art. 1348, 
 n. 39.) 
 
 Upon this point the Egyptian Code is clearer than the French 
 Code, which appears to say that any quasi-contract may be proved 
 by witnesses. (C. C. F. .1348.) But the authors are agreed 
 that what is intended is that such proof is admissible only when 
 the party could not have procured written proof. This is not 
 the case here. (Supra, p. 146.) 
 
 (2) No debt. 
 
 The plaintiff must prove that no debt, civil or natural, existed, 
 in satisfaction of which the payment was made. Or, to use the 
 language of the Egyptian Code, he must show that it was not the 
 payment of a civil debt or a voluntary payment in virtue of a 
 duty even not sanctioned by law . (C . C . E . 147/208 . See C . A . 
 Alex. 6 janv. 1903, B. L. J. XV, 79; C. A. Alex. 1 avril 1903, 
 B. L. J. XV, 220.; 
 
 This does not mean that he must range over all possible sources 
 of obligation and show negatively that he owes nothing to the 
 plaintiff under any of these heads. Such proof would be impos- 
 sible, for the sources would never be exhausted. 
 
 The plaintiff must prove that the payment was made in respect 
 of some particular debt and that this debt did not exist. In 
 many cases the receipt will indicate the supposed debt. In other 
 cases, the parties are agreed about it, and differ only as to its 
 existence or non-existence. When this is not so the plaintiff has 
 the onus of proving that the payment was on account of such 
 and such a debt. In most cases this is not very burdensome. 
 
QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 193 
 
 (3) Error. 
 
 As a rule the plaintiff must j)rove positively that he paid the 
 debt owing to an error. (Req. 9 mars 1909, D. 1910. 1. 103; 
 D. N. C. C. arts. 1376—1377, n. 200.) 
 
 But the kind of proof necessary varies very much according" 
 to the circumstances. It is urged by some writers that if the 
 plaintiff shows that no debt existed and that he made a payment, 
 a presumption thereupon arises that the payment was made in 
 error. It is for the defendant then to prove that the payment 
 was made voluntarily and in the knowledge that no debt existed. 
 There is a presumption against donation, hi re obscura melius 
 est favere repetitioni quam a3ventitio lucro. (D. 50. 17. 41; 
 Larombiere, on art. 1376, n. 31; Demolombe, 31, n. 286.) 
 
 But it is very doubtful if this is not too absolute a statement. 
 No doubt there is a presumption of fact that a man does not 
 throw his money away, but this makes it the more probable that 
 if there was a payment there was a debt. If the plaintiff denies 
 this, as he must, it is for him to prove why_Jie made the mistake. 
 (Laurent, 20, n. 368; Hue, 8, n. 389, 394; Cass. 25 nov. 1901. 
 D. 1903. 1. 549.) 
 
 Generally, this is not difficult. The two facts are so closely 
 involved that in proving the one he proves the other also. For 
 instance, a man is sued for a tradesman's account which he has 
 paid already. He cannot find the receipt, and he pays over again 
 in order to avoid execution on his property. 
 
 Subsequently, he finds the receipt and sues for repetition. The 
 production of the receipt and the proof of payment establish at 
 once the two points, viz.: (1) no debt; and (2) error. Payment 
 not having been pleaded in the first action the plaintiff cannot 
 be met with the plea of res judicata. (Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, 
 s. 769, p. 402; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2840.) 
 
 Or, suppose A, as his father's heir, pays a legacy to B, and 
 discovers afterwards that his father had revoked the legacy by a 
 codicil. He sues for repetition. When he has proved the pay- 
 ment and has to prove the non-existence of the debt, he produces 
 the codicil and this makes the proof of error very simple. 
 
 But cases are conceivable where, though the plaintiff proves that 
 no debt existed, and that, nevertheless, he made a payment,- these 
 facts do not raise any presumption of error. The presumption 
 may be that he made the payment to satisfy his conscience. A 
 
 W.— VOL. II. 13 
 
194 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 good example of this case is when the payment was of a debt 
 which had prescribed. But it is not necessary that there should 
 be a natural obligation. 
 
 The payment is not made in error if it is made to repair a 
 loss caused to another, or from the desire not to enrich oneself 
 at the expense of another. And such a payment does not require 
 for its validity the form prescribed for gifts. (Aubry et Rau, 
 4th ed. 4. p. 731; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 399.) 
 
 Moreover, when an account is presented and paid without 
 protest, the payer cannot recover merely by proving that the account 
 was excessive. He must show that there was error on his part. 
 
 So in a case in Quebec, where a certain quantity of stone was 
 to be delivered to a contractor by a fixed day, and a penalty of 
 so much a day was stipulated for delay after that time, it was 
 held that the contractor who had paid the price without deducting 
 the penalty which had been incurred could not recover the amount 
 of the penalty. 
 
 He had paid more than he really owed, but he had done so 
 voluntarily and without error. (Wighton v. Hitch, May 17, 
 1913, not reported.) 
 
 A payment made in the belief that a civil obligation exists may 
 be repeafed although there is a natural obligation. When the 
 code speaks of the voluntary discharge of an obligation it means 
 a payment made in the knowledge that no civil liability exists. 
 (Laurent, 17, n. 26; Demoloinbe, 27, n. 47; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 1674.) Upon this point the Arabic version of 
 C. C. E. 147/208 is puzzling. It says, "nevertheless, he who 
 willingly gives anything to another thinking himself bound to 
 pay has not the right to recover it." But probably this means 
 "thinking he is naturally' but not. civilly bound to pay." 
 
 Article C. C. E. 148/208 does not cover the case where a 
 person knowingly pays the debt of a third party. Here the 
 creditor does not receive what is not due to him and does not 
 enrich himself unjustly, and, therefore, if the person who has 
 paid fails to indemnify himself as a negotiorum gestor from the 
 real debtor, he cannot repeat from the creditor what he has paid 
 him. (Laurent, 20, n. 359; Larombiere, on art. 1377, n. 7; 
 C. A. Alex. 20 avril 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 274.) 
 
 Where the payment is dishonest but is received in good faith, 
 as whcn ; for example, an agent for two parties pays money which 
 belongs to one of them into the bank-account of the other, the 
 

 QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 195 
 
 party defrauded cannot recover from the "bank, because the payment 
 of money to a bank and the mixture of it with its other funds 
 according to the ordinary course of business, is equivalenl to the 
 consumption -which is sufficient to exclude the right to repeat 
 money or other fungibles. (C. C. F. 1238; C. C. Q. 1143; 
 Giraldi v. La Banque Jacques Cartier, 1884, R. J. Q. 9 Lower 
 Canada Reports, 597.) . . . 
 
 The other points in these articles are quite simple. 
 
 (1) The person receiving in good faith is a possessor in good 
 faith and, therefore, he is entitled to take the fruits during his 
 possession. He cannot be called upon to pay interest for the 
 money he has used. (C. A. Alex. 23 nov. 1899, B. L. J. XII, 
 27.) If the person receiving the payment was in bad faith he is 
 liable for interest on the money from the date at which he received j j 
 it. (C. C. F. 1378; Cass. 11 dec. 1900, D. 1901. 1. 257; Req. 
 17 nov. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 379.) 
 
 (2) It is not necessary first to put him in default; the liability 
 arises ipso jure from his taking the payment in bad faith. (C. 
 Alex. 19 nov. 1896, B. L. J. IX, 18; C. A. Alex. 8 fevr. 1898, 
 
 B. L. J. X, 127.) 
 
 For, if the person taking was in bad faith he is a possessor in 
 4>ad faith and must account for the fruits. The article in the 
 Quebec Code says that he must account for the profits which the 
 sum "ought to have produced from the time of receiving it, or 
 from the time that his bad faith began." (C. C. Q. 1049.) 
 The French Code and the Egyptian Code are silent as to this but 
 the law is the same. This is only according to the principle., 
 (Larombiere, on arts. 1378, 1379, n. 11.) 
 
 If the receiver is in bad faith the risk of the thing is with him. 
 But, probably, we may apply by analogy the principle stated in 
 
 C. C. F. 1302. If so, there is one case in which he can escape 
 his liability although he cannot return the thing, and that is if 
 he can show that it would equally have perished if it had been 
 in the possession of the owner. 
 
 If, for instance, the thing- which he had received was a horse 
 which had died of a disease, it might be easy to prove that it 
 would equally have died if it had remained in its owner's care. 
 (Aubry et Ran, 4th ed. 4, p. 736; B.-L. et Barde, 4, n. 2844. 
 Contra, Planiol, 2, n. 852. See, infra, p. 478. D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1379, n. 13.) 
 
 If the person who got the thing was in good faith he has no 
 liability for its loss, unless it perished by his fault. 
 
 13 2) 
 
196 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (3) Likewise if he was in good faith, and he alienates the thing 1 
 while his good faith continues, he is liable, in any event, only 
 for the price. (C. C. F. 1380; Demolombc, 31, n. 401; Aubry 
 et Rau, 4th ed. 4, p. 736; D. N. C. C. art. 1380. n. 19.) 
 
 (4) According to the general rule, whether the person receiving 
 the thing was in good or in bad faith, he is entitled to repeat 
 the money he has spent for the preservation of the thing, and 
 even those outlays which have increased its value. But as regards 
 the depenses utiles, the owner will be compelled to pay only to 
 the amount by which he is enriched. 
 
 For if the thing had been in the possession erf his owner, the, 
 neoesisary expenses would have been incurred, and the ameliora- 
 tions would have increased its value, so that, if the possessor could 
 not claim for them, the owner would be enriched at his expense. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, Ohlig. 4, n. 2847; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 4, 
 p. 737.) 
 
 English law as to quasi-contracts. 
 
 In its treatment of quasi-contracts, the common law takes a 
 narrower view than the civil law. The term quasi-contract is 
 just coming to be recognised in England, and in America it hasl 
 long been familiar. (See Pollock, Contracts, 8th ed. p. 14.) The 
 general principle underlying the doctrine of negotiorum gestjo 
 is not. accepted in the common law. That law does not allow a 
 man by a voluntary rendering of service to make another man 
 liable to him. 
 
 In the language of Lord Justice Bowen: " The general principle 
 is, beyond all question, that work and labour done or money 
 expended by one man to preserve or benefit the property of another 
 does not, by English law, create any lien upon the- pro- 
 perty saved or benefited, nor even, if standing alone, create any 
 obligation to repay the expenditure. Liabilities are not to be 
 forced upon people behind their backs any more than you can 
 confer a benefit upon a man against his will. 
 
 Thero is an exception to this proposition in the maritime 
 law. 
 
 With regard to salvage, general average, and contribution, the 
 maritime law differs from the common law. 
 
 That has been so from the time of the Roman law downwards." 
 (Falcke v. Scottish Imperial Insurance Co., 1886, 34 Ch. D. 
 
QUASI-CONTRACT RESULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 197 
 
 249, 56 L. J. Ch. 707, 713. As to conferring- a benefit see infra, 
 p. 447.) 
 
 And so it has been held that if one tenant-in-common of real 
 property expends money on its repair or improvement, the other 
 tenant is not liable to repay any portion of the money, merely 
 because he enjoys the benefit of the outlay while the tenancy-in- 
 common continues. {Leigh v. Dickeson, 1885, 1-5 Q. B. D. 60, 
 54 L. J. Q. B. 18.) The rule was stated by Brett, M.R., in that 
 case: " If one pays money voluntarily for another in such circum- 
 stances that the other is at liberty to accept or reject the advantage, 
 then if he adopts and ratifies that which was done for him he 
 becomes liable, although the payment was a voluntary payment. 
 But if the money is voluntarily expended in such circumstances 
 that the other is obliged to reap the advantage of it, the mere 
 fact of his having' accepted that which he was not at liberty to 
 refuse is no evidence of his adoption or ratification of the payment, 
 and the one who has made such voluntary payment must suffer 
 for his generosity." (See the notes to Lampleigh v. Brathivait, 
 in Smith's Leading' Cases, 11th ed. 1, 141.) 
 
 But although the doctrine of negotioriim gestio is not received 
 in the common law, there are, notwithstanding, certain classes 
 of cases in which a principle is accepted analogous to that which 
 is the basis of the action de in rem verso. In these cases the law 
 admits the right to claim the restoration of a benefit conferred 
 by the claimant but unjustly retained by the defendant, or to 
 claim its pecuniary equivalent. 
 
 Theory of implied contract. 
 
 The traditional way of explaining such cases is to say that a 
 contract is implied by law in the circumstances. (Blackstone, 
 Commentaries, III, 161.) The rule applicable when money has 
 been paid for another is stated thus: "Where a person has paid 
 money for another under circumstances and upon occasions which 
 make it just and equitable that it should be repaid; a debt or 
 promise to pay is then implied in law, without any actual agree- 
 ment to that effect." (See, per Maule, J., in Lewis v. Campbell, 
 1849, 8 C. B. 545, 79 R. R. 623. Cf. cases in Leake on Con- 
 tracts, 6th ed. p. 42.) 
 
 This introduction of a fictitious promise is artificial and 
 unnecessary, and when incapable persons are concerned the theory 
 breaks down. It is to be hoped that the English law will come 
 
198 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 to accept the term quasi-contract, or will find a better expression 
 to indicate that the obligation is created by law, and will abandon 
 the theory of implied contract in this kind of case. (See Pollock, 
 Contracts, 8th ed. p. 12.) 
 
 English illustrations of claims not arising from contract. 
 
 The following- examples ma} r suffice: — 
 
 In the maritime law one who saves or helps to save a vessel to 
 which he is a stranger from danger at sea is entitled to a reward 
 for his services, and the same rule applies to one who saves cargo 
 or other property, either while it is in the ship which is in peril 
 or after it has been thrown or washed out of her. The reward 
 paid to the salvors is called salvage. (See Gas Float Whit ton. 
 No. 2, 1896, P. 42, 65 L. J. P. 17; Carver, Carriage by Sea, 
 5th ed. s. 322.) 
 
 When a ship and cargo are exposed to a common danger of 
 damage or destruction and to avert it part of the cargo of the ship 
 is voluntarily sacrificed, this loss is divided equitably among the 
 owners of the property saved in proportion to the value of their 
 property which is saved. The loss is called a general-average 
 loss. (Whitecross Wire Co. v. Samll, 1882, 8 Q. B. D. 653, 
 51 L. J. Q. B. 426; Carver, Carriage by Sea, 5th ed. s. 361; 
 Halsbury, Laics of England, vo. Shipping and Navigation, p. 
 322.) 
 
 If one person be secondarily and another primarily liable for a 
 debt in respect of property in the enjoyment of the latter, and 
 the former has to pay, he is to be indemnified by the latter. 
 (Per Willes, J., in Roberts v. Crowe, 1872, L. R, 7 C. P. 629, 
 41 L. J. C. P. 198.) 
 
 " Where money is paid to another under the influence of a 
 mistake, that is upon the supposition that a specific fact is true 
 which would entitle the other to the money, but which fact is 
 untrue, and the money would not have been paid if it had been 
 known to the payer that the fact was untrue, an action will lie to 
 recover it back." (Kelly v. Solar i, 1841, 9 M. & W. 54, 60 R. ft. 
 666, per Parke, B.) 
 
 So also, it would seem that when an obligation is imposed upon 
 a person in the interest of the public and he fails to perform it, 
 another person who perforins the obligation with the expectation 
 of receiving compensation is entitled to recover what he has paid. 
 
 This has been repeatedly held in claims for repayment of funeral 
 
QUASI-CONTRACT RKSULTING FROM A PAYMENT NOT DUE. 199 
 
 expenses. So where the defendant who was possessed of a large 
 estate in Jamaica left his wife in England where she died, and 
 her father paid for her funeral expenses, it was held that the 
 father could recover from the husband. {Jenkins v. Tucker, 1 
 H. Bl. 90. Cf . Bradshm v. Beard, 1862, 12 C. B. N. S. 344, 
 133 R. R. 360; Keener, Quasi-Contracts, p. 341.) 
 
 The same principle applies when necessaries are supplied to a 
 person whom the defendant is bound by law to support but 
 neglects to do so, for instance, when necessaries are supplied to 
 defendant's wife who is living apart from her husband from no 
 fault of her own. (Baseley v. Forder, 1868, L. R. 3 Q. B. 559, 
 37 L. J. Q. B. 237; Johnston v. Sumner, 1858, 3 H. & N. 
 261, 117 R. R. 679. See Keener, Quasi-Contracts; p. 22.) 
 
 Another case is when necessaries have been supplied to a person 
 who is incapable of binding himself by contract. 
 
 The law implies an obligation on the part of a lunatic to pay 
 for necessaries supplied to him. {In re Rhodes, 1890, 44 Ch. D. 
 94, 59 L. J. Ch. 298.) 
 
 Cases of claims for services rendered by a housekeeper without 
 contract have been referred to above. (Supra, p. 182.) 
 
 In some of these cases the facts may point to an implied con- 
 tract, but in others the liability, if it exists at all, is quasi-con- 
 tractual. This must be so at all events when the defendant is a 
 lunatic or is otherwise incapable. (See In re Rhodes, ut supra.) 
 
 It is not necessary to explain here that peculiar kind of quasi- 
 contract of the common law which arises where there is what is 
 called a " waiver of tort." This happens in cases in which a person 
 has been injured by a tort by the commission of which the wrong- 
 doer has been enriched. 
 
 In some cases the (plaintiff instead of suing for damages sues to 
 recover the value of that which has been tortiously taken or is 
 being tortiously used by the defendant. He is allowed to "waive 
 the tort," as it is called, and sue in contract instead. But this 
 waiver of a tort is not allowed in every kind of case in which the 
 defendant has by his tort acquired a profit, and the limits of the 
 right to waive the tort are at present ill-defined. (Salmond, 
 Torts, 4th ed. p. 162; and, see, for illustrations, Scott, Cases on 
 Quasi-Contracts, pp. 106 seq. See, generally, on the subject of 
 quasi-contract i in the common law, Keener, Quasi-Contracts, New- 
 York, 1893; Scott, Cases on Quasi-Contracts, New York, 1905; 
 Salmond. Jurisprudence, 5th ed. 432; Encyelopcedia of Laws of 
 
200 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 England, s. v. Quasi-Contracts, ,and s. v. Negotiorum gestio ; 
 Beven, Negligence, 3rd ed. 2, p. 768; R. Campbell, Principles 
 of English Law, p. 408.) 
 
 Wrongs. 
 
 The obligations created by -wrongful acts and the remedies 
 provided by the law in cases of delict or quasi-delicts, as well as 
 the discussion upon, the nature of " fault " in the legal sense consti- 
 tute the law of responsibility, which is not covered in these volumes. 
 
OF OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM THE LAW SOLELY. 201 
 
 CHAPTER X. 
 
 OF OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM THE LAW SOLELY. 
 
 Like the French Code and the Code of Quebec, the Egyptian 
 Code forms a separate class of those obligations which result solely 
 from the operation of the law and independently of the will of 
 either of the parties, and are, moreover, not created by any act or 
 fait personnel. C. C. N. 154-157; C. C. M. 216—219; C. C, 
 F. 1370; C. C. Q. 1057.) 
 
 In a quasi-contract it is a lawful act which creates the obliga- 
 tion, and in one of them— ne got iorum gestio — we have seen that 
 the lawful act of the gerant creates various obligations by the 
 gerant himself as well as by the maitre or person benefited. 
 
 In a delict or in a ^quasi-delict there is a personal act,- and it js 
 this fait personnel of the wrong-doer which generates the obliga- 
 tion. 
 
 But in the case under consideration there is no personal act 
 which can be viewed as the source of the obligation. It is the 
 law, and only the law, which creates the liability. It has been 
 pointed out earlier that this classification of the sources of obliga- 
 tions is eminently unsatisfactory. It is much more scientific to 
 say that all obligations arise either from contract or from some 
 provision of the law. (See supra, p. 142. Planiol, Rev. Critique, 
 1904, 53, p. 224; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2787; Saleilles, 
 Theorie Generate de VObligation, 3rd ed. p. 449.) 
 
 Alimentary provisions. 
 
 In the Egyptian codes the only example mentioned of obliga- 
 tions resulting from the law solely is the obligation to pay an 
 alimentary provision to certain persons who are unable to support 
 themselves. This obligation is thrown by law upon certain 
 persons on account of their relationship by blood or by marriage to 
 those in need of the provision. 
 
 The French Code does not give this example in the general 
 
202 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 article on the .subject, but mentions instead certain obligations 
 of owners of adjoining properties, and the obligations of tutors 
 and other administrators who cannot refuse the office thrust upon 
 them by law. (C. C. F. 1370.) But in the French law, as in 
 the Egyptian, the duty to pay alimony is one of the most important 
 of the obligations resulting from the law solely. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 828; D. N. C. C. art. 1101, n. 13.) 
 
 With the special rules of alimony under the French Code we 
 are not here concerned. (See Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 153.) 
 
 Other obligations arising by law. 
 
 Before referring to the Egyptian rules on the subject, a word 
 may be said as to the examples given by the French Code of 
 obligations arising from the law solely. 
 
 If the tutor could choose whether he would accept or not, and 
 he accepted, his liability would be created by his voluntary act 
 of acceptance, but if the law compels him to act we may say that 
 the law makes ^him liable independently of any act of his. The 
 obligations which arise between neighbouring owners indepen- 
 dently of their will are really legal limitations of the powers of 
 an owner. If the law says that a man cannot open a window 
 having a direct view over his neighbour's land within less than a 
 metre of the neighbour's boundary, we may say, if we like, that 
 this is an obligation created by the law, or, " an obligation of 
 vicinity." But in the Egyptian Code these obligations are dealt 
 with under the head of servitudes,, and therefore they do not need 
 to be discussed here. (C. C. N. 30 seq.; C. C. M. 51 seq.) 
 
 It is not, perhaps, very scientific to call them servitudes, but 
 that is not a question which concerns us just now. Its discussion 
 belongs to the law of property. (See B.-L. et Chauveau, Biens, 
 n. 818; Hue, 8, n. 374; L'Egypte Contemporaine, VII, 184.) 
 
 All the obligations arising from status also result from the law, 
 because the consequences which flow from the possession of a 
 certain status are determined by the law irrespective of the will 
 of parties. It is true that a man may choose whether he will be 
 married or not, though he cannot choose whether he will be born 
 or not, and we may say that the obligations resulting from mar- 
 riage are not incurred without his will. But he is obliged to take 
 them as he finds them in the law. It is not his will which created 
 the obligations, although it depends on his will whether by getting 
 married he will accept the legal obligations of a married man or 
 not. 
 
OF OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM THE LA.W SOLELY. 203 
 
 Obligation of alimony in Egyptian Codes. 
 
 As regards the obligations of alimony the articles in the 
 Egyptian codes are very unsatisfactory for two reasons: — 
 
 (1) They are expressed in very vague language: and, 
 
 (2) They are on some points in conflict with the Mohammedan 
 law upon the subject, and yet alimony is a matter which must be 
 governed by the personal law. 
 
 The articles in the codes are as follows:— 
 
 (/ Descendants and persons connected by marrmge in the degree 
 of descendants, while the marriage lasts, are bound to make 
 alimentary provision for their ascendants or the p ersons connected 
 with them by marriage in the degree of ascendants. C. C. E. 
 155/217.) 
 
 The like obligation rests on ascendants as regards their des- 
 cendants or persons connected with them by marriage in the degree 
 of descendants, and on husband and wife as regards one (mother. 
 (C. C. E. 156/218.) 
 
 The amount of the alimentary provision is to be calculated 
 with regard to the needs of the party entitled and the resources of 
 the party liable. It is payable by the month and in advance. 
 (C. C. E. 157/219-220. 
 
 Analysis of article 155. 
 
 Article 155 of the Civil Code. 
 
 The following conclusions can be drawn from this article: — 
 
 (1) That the descendants are bound to make alimentary pro- 
 visions for their ascendants; 
 
 (2) That the descendants are bound to the wives of their ascen- 
 dants ; 
 
 (3) That the wives of the descendants are bound to their hus- 
 bands' ascendants so long as the marriage lasts; 
 
 (4) That the descendants' wives are bound to their ascendants' 
 waives . 
 
 Comparison with the Mohammedan law. 
 
 (1) This is true in the Mohammedan law. The jurists 
 (Alfokaha) have specified that the descendant is bound to his 
 ascendant on condition that the former be wealthy, without regard 
 to the latter's incapacity to earn his living provided he be poor. 
 (El Ahwal El Shakhssia, art. 408.) 
 
204 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (2) This is also true in the Mohammedan law. The jurists 
 have stated that the descendant is bound to the wife of his ascen- 
 dant, provided that the ascendant be in a state of illness which 
 necessitates that a wife should look after him. So if the ascendant 
 is connected by marriage with more than one person, the obligation 
 rests on the descendant to only one of his ascendant's wives. {Op. 
 cit. art. 409.) 
 
 (3) This is contrary to Mohammedan law, no jurist having 
 said that the wife of the descendant is bound to her husband's 
 ascendant. And, likewise, if the descendant be a woman, her 
 husband is not bound to her ascendants, even while, in both cases, 
 the marriage is still subsisting. 
 
 (4) This, again, is contrary to Mohammedan law. No jurist 
 has ever said that the wife of the descendant is bound to the wife 
 of the ascendant. 
 
 Analysis of article 156. 
 
 Article 156 of the Civil Code. 
 
 The following conclusions can be drawn from this article: — 
 
 (1) That the ascendants are bound to the descendants; 
 
 (2) That the ascendants are bound to the descendants' wives; 
 
 (3) That the wife is bound to her husband; 
 
 (4) That the husband is bound to his wife. 
 
 Comparison with the Mohammedan law. 
 
 (1) This is in accordance with the Mohammedan law. The 
 jurists have said that ascendants are bound to their descendants 
 provided the latter be poor. If the descendant is a man his ascen- 
 dants are bound to him until he is able to earn his living, and, if 
 the descendant is a woman, her ascendants are bound to her until 
 she gets married. But if before the woman marries, she is earn- 
 ing her living by a profession, no like obligation rests on her 
 ascendants. (Op. cit. arts. 395 and 396.) 
 
 (2) According to Mohammedan law, an ascendant is not bound 
 to his descendant's wife unless the descendant is poor, incapable 
 of earning his living and in a state of illnes6 in which he is in 
 need of assistance. {Op. cit. art. 409.) 
 
 (3) There is no such rule in the Mohammedan law. "How- 
 ever large the fortune of the woman may be she is not held liable 
 to contribute to the expenses incumbent on the husband." (Kadri 
 Pasha, Mohammedan Personal Law, s. 206.) 
 
OF OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FKOM THE LAW SOLELY. 20-5 
 
 (4) This is true in the Mohammedan law. The jurists have 
 agreed that a husband is bound to his wife even if she is rich. 
 Among- persons entitled to alimony, the wife alone has a right to 
 it even if she is rich. (Kadri Pasha, s. 160.) 
 
 Code speaks only of ascendants, descendants, and spouses. 
 
 In addition to the discrepancies above referred to between the 
 rules given in the civil code as to the obligation to make an alimen- 
 tary provision, and those of the Mohammedan Personal Law, 
 there is in the articles of the code a singular omission. The code 
 speaks only of the obligation as regards ascendants and descen- 
 dants, and husband and wife. But by the Mohammedan Personal 
 Law, Maintenance is due to every relative with whom marriage 
 is prohibited, when he is without means and in need oj receiving 
 charity, from his presumptive heir, even if a minor, in proportion 
 to his share of inheritance. (Kadri Pasha, s. 415.) 
 
 The meaning of the section is that the duty of maintenance, 
 exists between persons who are within the degrees in which mar- 
 riage is prohibited, whether these persons are of the same sex or 
 of different sexes. And the Mohammedan law lays down precise 
 rules as to the effect upon this obligation of a difference in religion 
 between the relatives, and as to the extent of the duty when there 
 are several relatives in the same prohibited degree. (Sections 
 416 — 418.) And further, "The distant kindred, with whom 
 marriage is not prohibited, are discharged of the obligation of 
 maintenance when there is a relative with whom marriage is pro- 
 hibited." (Sect. 417.) 
 
 Upon all this the code is quite silent. (For this comparison 
 with the Mohammedan law I am largely indebted to my colleague 
 Sheikh Mohammed Zeid El Ibiani, Bey.) 
 
 Egyptian jurisprudence. 
 
 The conflict between the law stated in the code and the Moham- 
 medan Personal Law creates in practice no difficulty, owing to 
 the fact that the articles in the code are treated as a dead letter. 
 Questions of maintenance where Egyptians are concerned come, 
 before the courts having jurisdiction in matters of personal status, 
 and these courts apply the Mohammedan law without reference 
 to the provisions of the code. 
 
200 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XI. 
 
 * PUTTING IN DEFAULT— MISE EN DEMEURE. 
 
 Before the debtor in a contract is liable in damages three con- 
 ditions must be fulfilled: — 
 
 (1) The non -performance must have caused prejudice to the 
 creditor, and this prejudice must be an immediate and direct 
 result thereof; 
 
 (2) The non -performance must be due to the fault of the debtor 1 ; 
 and, 
 
 (3) The debtor must have been put in default. 
 
 And under the term' non-performanoe we must include the 
 partial as well as the complete failure to execute the obligation at 
 the proper time. Whether the failure is complete or partial there 
 is non-performanoe in the legal sense. (C. O. E. 119, 120/177, 
 178; C. C. F. 1146, 1147; C. C. Q. 1067, 1070.) 
 
 It is with the third of these conditions that we are now con-> 
 cerned. The failure to execute the obligation or the delay in its 
 performance must be established in a legal way. It must be, as 
 the old French writers said, un retard officiellement constate et 
 vmputable an debiteur. (Bourjon, Droit de la France, 2, Liv. 
 6, Tit. 1, ch. 7, s. 7, p. 445; Saleilles, Theorie Generale 
 de V Obligation, 3rd; ed. p. 24.) The fact that the debtor 
 has failed to fulfil his obligation in due time cannot as a general 
 rule be established until there has been a formal demand made 
 upon him by the creditor to execute his obligation. It is this 
 formal demand which is called " putting him in default " or a 
 mise en demeure. (C. C. E. 120/178 says broadly damages 
 are not recoverable so long as the debtor is not in default.) 
 This broad statement requires, however, as will be seen, consider- 
 able qualification. But, undoubtedly, the general principle of the 
 law is that until the creditor has -put the debtor in default the 
 presumption is that the creditor considers that the delay in per- 
 formance does not cause him any prejudice, and that he consents 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT— MISE EN DEMEURE. 207 
 
 to it. (B.-L. et Bardc, Oblig. 1, n. 408; Planiol, 2, n. 168; 
 Eteq. Ler dec. 1897, D. 98. 1. 289, and note by M. Planiol; 
 1). N. C. C. art. 1139, n. 1; C. A. Alex. 17 mars 1898, B. L. J. 
 X, 203; C. A. Alex. 15 avril 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 200.) 
 
 Mise en demeure. 
 When a date has been fixed for performance. 
 
 When no time for the performance of the obligation has been 
 fixed expressly or by implication, it is natural to hold that the 
 debtor is not in default. (Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 14.) But 
 even when a date for its performance has been expressly stipulated 
 the mise en demeure is still necessary unless the case falls under 
 one of the exceptions to be presently explained. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 1001; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 150; C. A. Alex. 
 18 avril 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 200.) 
 
 The necessity for a mise en demeure is a traditional rule of the 
 old French law. The old French commentators on the Roman 
 law, notably Cujas and Doneau, believed that the Roman law 
 was to the opposite effect, and that under it when a term for pay- 
 ment had been fixed, the expiration of this term put the debtor 
 in default without any formal demand by the creditor. The 
 glossarists expressed this by saying dies inter pellat pro homine. 
 
 This does not appear to be a correct interpretation of the Roman 
 texts. In the Roman law the rule was" that a mise en demeure 
 or interpellatio was necessary in this case also, unless upon the 
 interpretation of the contract there was evidence of a contrary 
 intention. (Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 648; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 1001;- Saleilles, Theorie Generale de V Obligation, 
 p. 24.) 
 
 Mise en demeure in commercial matters. 
 
 In the French law and the law of Egypt the rule that the debtor 
 must be put .in default before damages are due applies to com- 
 mercial as well as to civil contracts. But in commercial matters 
 the mise en demeure, as explained later, may be made in a less 
 formal manner. So in Egypt it has been held that demurrage— 
 surestaries — does not begin to run until after there has been a. 
 mise en demeure. Surestaries are the sums to be paid for detain- 
 ing a ship while loading or unloading for a longer period than 
 was specified. (Lyon-Caen et Renault, Manuel de Droit Com- 
 mercial, n. 935; C. A. Alex. 9 mai 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 237.) 
 
208 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The same rule that it is necessary to put the debtor in default 
 applies to the sale of merchandise unless the contract can be 
 brought under one of the excepted cases. 
 
 The law is thus stated in the head-note of a recent decision 
 by the Mixed Court of Appeals: 
 
 Ce n'est qu'a litre d'exception que le vendeur pent se trouver 
 en demeure par le seid fait de respiration du delai fixe pour la 
 livraison, lorsque les cir Constances de la cause rendent evident e 
 Vintention des parties de faire, de V observation du delai, hme obli- 
 gation essentielle du vendeur: il en est ainsi notamment lorsque 
 le plus leger retard est de nature a causer un prejudice important. 
 Autrement, la regie generate qui impose la necessite d'une mise en 
 demeure reprend son empire, et elle est d'autant plus facile a 
 suivre, en matiere commercials, qu'un simple telegramme suffit 
 pour y satisfaire. (C. A. Alex. 12 fevr. 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 
 170.) 
 
 How the debtor is put in default. 
 
 The Egyptian Code is completely silent as regards the manner 
 of putting the debtor in default; it is, however, settled by the 
 jurisprudence that the French rules on the subject are followed 
 in Egypt. The French Code says that unless there is an agree- 
 ment to the contrary the debtor is put in default soit par un-e 
 sommation ou par autre acte equivalent. (C. C. F. 1139.) And 
 it is a question of fact if the acte addressed to the debtor is 
 expressed in sufficiently formal terms to constitute a mise en 
 demeure. (Cass. 25 avril 1893, D. 93. 1. 350; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 1, n. 427.) 
 
 A writ of summons is such an acte and so is the commande- 
 ment, or monition of execution, by which a creditor having an 
 executory title declares in a formal way his intention to execute 
 a seizure after the legal delay. (Planiol, 2, n. 169. See C. Pro. 
 E. 384/437; Lusena, Procedure Civile, 2, p. 19. Cf. Cass. 6 
 juill. 1909, D. 1909. 1. 510.) 
 
 But without the commencement of any legal procedure the 
 creditor can put his debtor in default by a formal demand served 
 upon him by a bailiff calling upon him to execute his obligation. 
 And it is this sommation par exploit d.liuissier which is the con- 
 secrated form of putting a debtor in default. In fact the only 
 safe course is always to begin by an extrajudicial demand, for, 
 if the creditor begins with a judicial demand, and then the debtor 
 at once consents to the performance of the obligation the debtor is 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEURE. 209 
 
 entitled to payment of the costs of the action. In civil matters, 
 apart from agreement to the contrary, the debtor cannot be put 
 in default by a letter, for a letter cannot be an acte equivalent to 
 a sommation. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 427.) 
 
 There is an arret of the Chambre des Requites in a civil case 
 which refused to find that the judges of the court below had erred 
 in admitting the sufficiency of mise en demeure by a letter. But 
 this judgment has been adversely criticised and remains isolated. 
 (Req. 5 dec. 1883, D. 84. 1. 130; Hue, 7, n. 117; Planiol, 2, 
 n. 169; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 15.) 
 
 A fortiori, a verbal demand in a civil matter cannot effect a 
 mise en demeure, (C. A. Alex. 21 dec. 1911, B. L. J. XXIV, 
 59.) 
 
 But in commercial matters by usage the French law has greatly 
 relaxed the rule which requires that the mise en demeure shall 
 be by a formal acte. It is settled that in commercial matters the 
 debtor may be put in default by a letter and even by a telegram. 
 (Cass. 28 oct. 1903, S. 1908. 1. 422; Bordeaux, 17 dec. 1895, 
 D. 97. 2. 507; Thaller, Traite Elementaire de Droit Commercial, 
 4th ed. n. 1052; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Com- 
 mercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 32.) 
 
 This may be supported as a matter of construction of the French 
 Code by the argument that in 'commercial matters the parties 
 have agreed to be governed by business usages, so that the mise 
 en demeure, although not made by an acte, is made in a manner 
 contemplated by the parties. 
 
 Under the Egyptian Code there is no difficulty in admitting 
 this practice, seeing that the code does not prescribe any .form for 
 the mise en demeure. And it is settled by the jurisprudence in 
 Egypt that in commercial matters the debtor may be put in 
 default in this way. (C. A. Alex. 12 fevr. 1913, B. L. J. 
 XXV, 170; C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1899, B. L. J. XII, 40.) 
 
 And in commercial matters, according to some French autho- 
 rities, even a verbal demand may be sufficient to put the debtor 
 in default. (Planiol, 2, n. 169.) Probably this may be a matter 
 of usage. In certain businesses a verbal demand may be recog- 
 nised in practice. But unless there is clear proof of such a custom 
 in a particular trade it does not seem that such a manner of putting 
 a debtor in default ought to be recognised by the court. (See 
 Demolombe, 24, n. 525; C. A. Alex. 21 dec. 1911, B. L. J. 
 XXIV, 59; C. A. Alex. 16 mars 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 333.) 
 
 W.— VOL. II. I J 
 
210 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Iu one important case which frequently occurs, it has been held 
 in Quebec that a party may be put in default by a notice in a 
 newspaper. This is where a notice by a ship's agent is placed in 
 a newspaper published in the port of destination of a ship, signi- 
 fying the arrival of the ship and calling upon the consignees to 
 take delivery within a certain delay of the goods consigned to 
 them. 
 
 After the lapse of this delay, if the goods have not been re- 
 moved, the contract of carriage is at an end by the default of the 
 consignees to take delivery in due time, and the carrier from 
 that time holds the goods as a warehouseman, and is not liable 
 for their loss by theft, etc. without proof of fault. (Grothe v. 
 Canada Line, 1912, R. J. Q. 42 S. C. 443.) 
 
 In places where such advertisements are recognised by com- 
 mercial usage this conclusion seems to be in accordance with 
 principle. 
 
 In the case of a bill of exchange or of a promissory note which 
 has not been paid at maturity, the protest of the bill made by a 
 bailiff is a mise en demeure of the parties liable on the bill if the 
 holder exercises his recourse within the legal delays. (See C. 
 Comm. E. 162/169; Thaller, Trait e Elementaire de Droit Com- 
 mercial, 4th ed. n. 1545.) 
 
 Where no mise en demeure is necessary. 
 
 The Egyptian Code throws no light upon this subject. There 
 are, notwithstanding, a number of important cases, in which on 
 the principles of the French law it is clear that no mise en demeure 
 is required. Several of these are stated or implied in articles of 
 the French Code, and there is no doubt that upon this matter 
 the law of Egypt is the same. 
 
 These cases may be thus classified: — 
 
 (a) When it is no longer possible to fulfil the obligation. 
 
 (b) When there is a text of the law which says that the debtor 
 shall be in default without any mise m demeure. 
 
 (c) When there is a (stipulation express or implied dispensing 
 the creditor from the necessity of putting his debtor in default ., 
 (Planiol, 2, n. 170; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 469.) 
 
 (d) When the obligation has its source in a delict or in a 
 quasi-delict. (Req. 4 fevr. 1868, D. 68. 1. 271; Colin et Capi- 
 tant. 2, p. 16.) > 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEUKE. 211 
 
 These cases will be considered in order. 
 
 (a) Performance impossible. 
 
 (1) In the case of an obligation not to do something it would 
 be futile to require the creditor to call upon the debtor to keep 
 his contract after he had already broken it. This rule is expressly; 
 stated in the French Code. (C. C. F. 1145.) It must be under- 
 stood to be implied in the Egyptian Code. If a man has con- 
 tracted not to build a wall, or not to sing at a theatre, and he 
 has broken his contract, a mise en demeure could serve no purpose. 
 (Demolombe, 24, n. 541; Laurent, 16, n. 240; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 1, n. 444; D. N. C. C. art. 1145, n. 2.) 
 
 (2) When the thing which the debtor was bound to give or to 
 do could only be given or done within a certain time which he has 
 allowed to expire, no mise en demeure is required. (C. C. F. 
 1146.) Here the mere delay in the execution of the obligation 
 amounts to an impossibility of executing it. (See the note by 
 M. Planiol to Cass. 11 janv. 1892, D. 92. 1. 257.) They are 
 cases in which, as English lawyers express it, " time is of the 
 essence of the contract." 
 
 Although no time is stipulated the matter is obviously one which 
 can only be done within a certain delay. It is a matter of urgency 
 and this is understood by both parties. If I instruct my advocate 
 to appeal from a judgment, he knows that the appeal must be 
 entered within a certain delay, and if he fails to do so the fulfil- 
 ment of the contract becomes impossible. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 147; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 469; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 151.) 
 
 If a merchant undertakes to send goods to be shipped by a 
 certain vessel, he cannot fulfil his contract by sending them after 
 the ship has sailed. If a florist undertakes to send flowers for 
 the bridesmaids at a wedding, he cannot fulfil the contract the day 
 after the ceremony. In commercial matters, especially, there are 
 many cases in which a delay in the performance may amount to 
 an impossibility of performing the obligation according to the 
 intention of the parties. 
 
 We may in these cases explain the rule that no mise en demeure 
 is necessary by saying that there is a tacit agreement dispensing 
 the creditor from the necessity of putting the debtor in default., 
 (Demolombe, 24, nos. 513, 542; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 151; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 170; Req. 30 janv. 1911, D. 1912. 1. 48; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1139, n. 45.) 
 
 14 2) 
 
212 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (3) When one of the parties to a contract has repudiated it, 
 and declared that he does not consider himself to be bound by it, 
 it is not necessary for the other party to put him in default... 
 (C. A. Alex. 14 juin 1900, B. L. J. XII, 350.; And in like 
 manner, when a party has intimated to the other party that ho 
 finds it impossible to fulfil his obligation, no mise en demeure is 
 necessary. This has been held recently in a case where the debtor 
 had undertaken to supply a cargo and he intimated that he was 
 unable to do so, and begged the shipowner to procure a cargo 
 elsewhere. (C. A. Alex! 28 janv. 1918, B. L. J. XXX, 168.) 
 
 (4) It is not necessary to put the debtor in default when he 
 has broken his contract not merely by not having fulfilled it 
 within the time specified, but by having done something which 
 makes its performance impossible. So where the seller of a corps 
 certain notifies the buyer that he has sold and delivered the thing 
 to another there is no need to put him in default. (C. A. Alex. 
 23 mars 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 167.) 
 
 And in a Quebec case, where a man had contracted to construct 
 a baker's oven and had performed the -work in an unscientific 
 way and was unable to put it right, it was held in an action of 
 damages for the expense of rebuilding the oven that no mise en 
 demeure was necessary. (Vermette v. Parent, 1910, R. J. Q. 
 20 K. B. 156.) 
 
 English law as to this. 
 
 So, likewise, in the English law, when there is an express- 
 promise to do a thing and the party by his own act makes it 
 impossible that he should perform his promise, there is a breach, 
 of contract from that moment. [Ogdens. Ltd. v. Nelson, 1905, 
 A. C. 109; 74 L. J.. K. B. 433. 
 
 Putting in default presupposes possibility of performance. 
 
 The previous cases illustrate the general principle which may 
 be stated thus: — 
 
 Putting in default presupposes that it is still possible to per- 
 form the obligation. 
 
 It is a formal demand upon the debtor to perform his contract 
 without further delay accompanied by an intimation that the 
 creditor will hold the debtor responsible for the damage caused 
 by the delay. Such a demand has no meaning when it has already 
 become impossible to perform the contract, and that owing to 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEUKE. 213 
 
 the fault of the debtor, as, for example, if he has by his negligence 
 permitted the destruction of the thing which he was bound to 
 deliver, or if he has done something which he has bound himself 
 not to do. 
 
 Where putting in default is required it is because the law pro- 
 ceeds upon the view that until the debtor has received the formal 
 notification he is not in default. But such a position is untenable 
 when there has been an actual fault on the part of the debtor which 
 makes it impossible for him to fulfil his contract. (Baudry- 
 Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 3rd ed. 1, n. 472; Planiol, 2, 
 n. 227.) 
 
 (b) Law may declare mise en demeure unnecessary. 
 
 There are a number of cases in which the French Code says 
 that a debtor shall be liable for loss caused even by cas fortuit, 
 or that interest shall run against him from a certain date de plein 
 droit, and in these cases no mise en demeure is necessary. (B.-L. 
 ct Barde, 1, n. 469; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 151; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1139, n. 61.) 
 
 The principal cases are :— 
 
 (1) When a thing stolen is destroyed in the hands of the thief 
 or of a person who has received it knowing it to have been stolen, 
 the thief or the receiver is liable to restore the value without any 
 mise en demeure. (C. C. P. 1302; C. C. Q. 1200.) The Egyp- 
 tian codes have no similar provision, but, probably, the same rule 
 would be followed. For the obligation is not here contractual, 
 and the policy of the law is to discourage thieves and receivers 
 of stolen goods. ;B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 192-5. Cf. C. A. Alex. 
 19 nov. 1896, B. L. J. IX, 18.) 
 
 (2) Any one who has received in bad faith what is not due to 
 him is responsible for its restitution or for its value if it has been 
 lost, and for the interest and fruits. He cannot say his liability 
 is only from the date of the mise en demeure. (C. C. E. 145, 
 146/206, 207; C. C. F. 1378; C. A. Alex. 19 nov. 1896, B. L. 
 J. IX, 18.) 
 
 (3) The mandatary who has employed for his own use money 
 which he has received on account of the mandator owes the interest 
 from the date when this improper use began. (C. C. E. 526/646; 
 C. C. F. 1996.) 
 
 (4) The borrower who has employed the thing for a use not 
 contemplated by the lender, or for a time longer than was con- 
 templated, is under the French Code liable for the loss of the 
 
214 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 thing even though this is caused by a fortuitous event. (C. C. F. 
 1881.) 
 
 No mise en demeure is needed to create this liability. 
 
 The Egyptian codes do not contain the statement that the bor- 
 rower in such a case bears all the risks, and it is difficult to imply 
 such a provision. (C. C. E. 470/572.) 
 
 (c) Stipulation may make mise en demeure unnecessary. 
 
 No misfi en demeure is required when it was stipulated in 
 the contract that the mere failure of the debtor to execute the 
 contract should put him in default. The clause usually runs 
 il sera repute en demeure sans qa'il soit besoin d'acte et par la 
 seule echeance du terme.^ (B.-L. et Barde, Ohlig. 1, n. 469: 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4,p. 151; D. N. C. C. art. 1139, n.j33.) 
 
 But no terms are sacramental, and the court may find that other 
 expressions used by the parties sufficiently indicate their intention 
 to dispense* with any mise en demeure. (B.-L. et Barde, ib.\ 
 Cass. 6 juill. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 510; Req. 18 fevr. 1853. D. 
 56. 1. 260; C. A. Alex. 6 janv. 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 125.) So, 
 in the sale of merchandise, when a time has been fixed for delivery, 
 and it is stipulated that the buyer shall have the right to refuse 
 any goods not sent en temps utile, no mise en demeure is necessary. 
 (C. A. Alex. 29 mai 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 368; Gaz. des Trib. 
 2, p. 193. Cf . C. A. Alex. 30 janv. 1901, B. L 1 . J. XIII, 125.) 
 And where there are no express terms dispensing the creditor from 
 a mise en demeure the court may find that such a stipulation was 
 implied. (B.-L. et Barde, I.e.; D. N. C. C. art. 1139, n. 45.) 
 But the evidence of intention to dispense with the mise en demeure 
 must be plain. When there is a clause in a contract rendering 
 the whole debt immediately payable on failure to pay any one 
 of the instalments, such clause can only be enforced after default 
 resulting from formal demand, unless there is an express provi- 
 sion to the contrary., (Trib. Somm. Kafr el Sheikh, 28 mai 
 1918,0. B. XX, n. 10.) 
 
 Waiver of right to insist on mise en demeure. 
 
 Even when there is an express stipulation in the contract that 
 the debtor shall be put in default by the mere expiration of the 
 term, it may be found that the creditor has by his conduct waived 
 his right to found upon the default. In policies of fire insurance 
 a clause is generally inserted to the following effect: En defaut de 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEURE. 215 
 
 paiement de la prime dan- !>■ delai fixe, et sans quHl soit besoin 
 d'aucune mise en demeure, V assure n'a droit, an cas de sinistre, 
 a aucune indemnite. 
 
 In many cases it has been held in France that the infliirajobei- 
 company could not take advantage of this stipulation when they 
 had been in the habit of sending their agent or collector to the 
 domicile of the assured to collect the premiums. In spite of the 
 clause in the policy, there was no default until this demand had 
 been made; because the company had given the assured a right 
 to expect it. (Paris, 2 mars 1893, D. 93. 2. 256; D. N. C. C. 
 IV, p. 875, nos. 1108 seq. But the fact that an insurant - 
 company collected some of its premiums in this way from other 
 persons would not prevent the clause in the policy from producing 
 its effect in the case of an assured who had always taken his 
 premiums to the company. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1511; 
 Cass. 4 nov. 1891, D. 92. 1. 313. 
 
 (d) No mise en demeure necessary when action based on 
 
 wrong-doing. 
 
 It would be unreasonable to allow a person who had eaufi d 
 damage to another by his wrong-doing to be free from liability 
 until he had received a formal demand. His liability is directly 
 created by the law and it exists from the moment of the wrong. 
 .(Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 149. note 1: B.-L. et Bard©, 1, 
 n. 4730 
 
 Effects of putting in default. 
 
 Except in the special cases which have been referred to. the law 
 presumes that although the debtor has not fulfilled his obligation 
 at the proper time the delay does not cause any damage to the 
 creditor. It is presumed that the creditor is allowing the debtor 
 to take his time for performing his obligation. But when the 
 creditor puts the debtor in default this is a clear indication that 
 he considers himself to be suffering prejudice by the delay. 
 The effects of putting the debtor in default are: — 
 (1) Damages become due. The Egyptian codes state clearly 
 that they are not recoverable as long as the debtor is not in default. 
 (C. C. E. 120/178.) The amount of the damages will need to 
 be ascertained or liquidated by the court unless it has been stated 
 by the parties that in case of inexecution a certain fixed amount 
 is to be'paid. In this case the judge cannot modify the amount 
 
216 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 of the damages so stipulated. (C. C. E. 123/181; C. C. F. 
 1152; C. C. Q. 1076.) 
 
 But when the damages have not been fixed in this way by the 
 parties, and have to be liquidated by the court, they must be 
 calculated not from the time of the breach of contract, but from 
 the date of the mise en demeure. 
 
 The creditor is presumed to have waived his right to claim 
 damages suffered before the mise en demeure, and, as M. Barde 
 expresses it, au point de vue legal, le prejudice anterieur a la mise 
 en demeure n'existe pas. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 468;, 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 150; Cass. 11 janv. 1892, D. 92. 
 1. 257; C. A. Alex. 9 mai 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 237.) 
 
 Mr. Halton is of opinion that the Egyptian law differs from 
 the French law upon this point. He says of the view that pre- 
 judice anterior to the formal demand in the eyes of the law has 
 no existence: ".It seems to be untenable in Egypt on account of 
 the word employed ' recoverable,' which seems to imply that the 
 right to damages was already in existence." (1, p. 270.) 
 
 But with all respect, it does not appear that any such stress 
 can fairly be laid upon this word which is used in the English 
 version of C. C. N. 120. No word equivalent to "recoverable" 
 occurs in the Arabic version. 
 
 The French version simply says les dommages-interet* ne sont 
 dus taut que le debiteur nrtmt pas en dem.eure, and the view that} 
 damages anterior to the mise en demeure can be recovered is 
 inconsistent with general principles. 
 
 When the object of an obligation is the payment of a sum of 
 money the damages consist of the legal interest unless there is a 
 stipulation to the contrary or some special provision of law. 
 
 And the damages or interest for the breach of a money obliga- 
 tion are not due even from a mise en demeure. There must be 
 a commencement of legal proceedings — demande en justice. 
 (C. C. E. 124/182.) 
 
 This question will be considered in speaking of the measure of 
 damages. ' 
 
 <;2) The second effect of putting in default is that a change 
 takes place in regard to the risk. When the debtor is in default 
 he is in fault, and, if owing to his default, a thing in his care 
 is lost or damaged the liability will fall upon him. Qui in mora 
 est culpa nan meat. For instance, if a man has sold a horse, 
 and is in default in not having delivered it, and the stable is burnt 
 
PUTTING IN DEFAULT — MISE EN DEMEUKE. 217 
 
 down and the horse killed, the loss will fall on the seller, though 
 if the fire was not due to the negligence of the seller or his sell ants, 
 the loss would in the French law have been on the buyer but for 
 the default. 
 
 But in such a case, the debtor will escape his liability although 
 he is in default, if he can show that the loss was not due to his 
 default. Thus, in the illustration given, the seller would be excused 
 if his stable adjoined that of the buyer, and both stables had been 
 burnt down in the lire by which the horse perished, so that even 
 if the horse had been delivered at the proper time it would have 
 perished just the same. (C. C. E. 178/241; C. C. F. 1302; 
 C. C. Q. 1200; Pothier, Oblig. n. 664; Vente, n. 58; Hue, 8, 
 n. 182.) 
 
 Unless this defence is available the seller bears the loss, because 
 he cannot say that the thing sold perished without his fault. 
 (C. C. E. 178/241.) 
 
 But upon this matter of risk in sale the Egyptian law is, 
 probably, different. It is hard to reconcile the articles of the code 
 on the subject, but the better opinion is that the risk is on the 
 vendor, even though he is not in default. (C. C. E. 266/336; 
 297/371; Grandmoulin, Contrats, n. 58; De Hults, Rep. vo. 
 Bisques, n. 13; and Vente, n. 118, and n. 133; Halton, 2, p. 27. 
 Infra, 2, p. 481.) 
 
 If this view is correct, the default does not, in the Egyptian 
 law, change the risk in this case. It does, however, change it in 
 the following case: — 
 
 When the purchaser has been put in default to take delivery 
 and, thereafter, the thing sold perishes without the fault of the 
 seller the loss falls on the purchaser. The seller can claim the 
 price. (C. C. E. 297/371; C. C. F. 1624; Pothier, Vente, n. 55; 
 Laurent, 16, n. 249.) 
 
 Mise en demeure in other codes. 
 
 It is very doubtful whether the French law has done well to 
 retain the rule that when a term of performance is fixed by the 
 contract, and it has expired without the contract being fulfilled, 
 there is still no breach unless the debtor has been put in default. 
 It is significant that most modern codes have dispensed with the 
 necessity for a mise en demeure when the contract has fixed a date 
 of performance. According to the German Code, no mise en 
 demeure is necessary when the time of performance is fixed for 
 
218 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 a certain day according- to the calendar, such as " on the fifth' 
 May 1913 "; "at Christmas, 1913 "; "in November of this year," 
 etc. (art. 284. See Cosack, LehrbucJi d&s Deutseheji burger- 
 lichen Rechts, 6th ed. 1, p. 421.) 
 
 The Swiss Federal Code of Obligations is to a similar effect 
 (art. 102), and so is the Italian Civil Code (art. 1223). The 
 Code of Quebec distinguishes between civil and commercial con- 
 tracts. In civil contracts there must be a mise en demeure, 
 though it does not need to be by an acte d'huissier, but in all 
 contracts of a commercial nature in which the time of performance 
 is fixed, the debtor is put in default by the mere lapse of such time. 
 (C. C. Q. 1069.) 
 
 And in commercial cases the courts hold that, though no time 
 has been expressly fixed in the contract for the performance, the 
 law implies that the contract shall be performed in a reasonable 
 time, and if this time has elapsed without performance the debtor 
 is in default. 
 
 No mise en demeure required in English law. 
 
 In the English law there is no rule requiring the plaintiff to 
 make a formal demand upon the defendant to perform his contract. 
 The right of action for damages arises directly from the breach 
 of the contract. (See Anson, Contracts, 14th ed. p. 344.) 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 219 
 
 CHAPTER XII. 
 
 REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 
 
 The general rules on this subject are thus given in the Egyptian 
 Native Code: — 
 
 When the debtor refuse* to perform in its entirety whqi he is, 
 bound to perform, the creditor has the choice either of demanding 
 the rescission of the contract together with damages, or of de- 
 manding damages for the unperformed part. 
 
 Nevertheless, the creditor may, if the cwcumstcmces of the. 
 case permit, obtain leave of the court to execute, at the expense 
 of the debtor, that which such debtor was bound to perform, or to 
 undo that ichitili has been done contrary to the agreement . 
 
 When, the obligation is to transfer a specific corporeal thing 
 the creditor may have himself put in possession thereof, provided 
 such thing urns owned by the debtor at the time when the obliga- 
 tion came into existence or since that time, and provided that no 
 third person has acquired a real right over it (arts. 117. 118). 
 
 The Mixed Code is to the same effect, but it contains, in addi- 
 tion, a separate article: The rescission of a contract, whereby the 
 ownership of immoveables is transferred, does not prejudice the 
 rights of registered mortgage er editors. ( (C. C. M. 173 — 176.) 
 
 With these articles of the Egyptian Code we must compare the 
 corresponding articles of the French Code. These are the follow- 
 ing:— 
 
 La condition resolutoire est toujours sous-entehdue dans tes 
 controls synallagmatiqaes, pour le cas oil Tune des deux parties 
 ne satisfera point a son engagement. 
 
 Dans oe cas, le control riest point resolu de plein droit. La 
 partie envers laquelle V engagement na point ete execute, a le 
 cihoix oude forcer Vautye a V execution de la convention lorsqu'elle 
 est possible, ou d'eoi demander la resolution aver dommages et 
 interets. 
 
 La resolution doit etre demandee en justice, et il pent etre 
 accorde au defendeur un delai selon les circonstanoes (art. 1184). 
 
220 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Toute obligation de faire ou de ne pa* faire 8e resout en dom- 
 mages et interets, en cm d'inexecution de la part du debiteur. 
 
 Neanmoins U oreander a le droit de dcmander que ce qui 
 await ete fait par contravention a I 'engagement, soit detruit ; et 
 il pent se faire autoriser a le detruire aux depens du debiteur, 
 sans prejudice des dommages et interets s'il y a lieu. 
 
 Le creancier pent aussi, en cas aVinexecution, etre autorise a 
 faire executer lui-meme Vobligation aux depens du debiteur 
 (arts. 1142—1144. Cf. C. C. Q. 1065, 10(56). 
 
 The rules on the subject are traditional and they are not ex- 
 pressed in the codes by any means in a scientific manner. It is 
 clear, however, from perusal of the articles that the right of a 
 creditor, when there has been a breach of the contract, varies 
 according to circumstances. There are a number of remedies, but 
 they are not all available in each case. 
 
 Every obligation renders the debtor liable to damages in case 
 of a breach of it on his part. In some cases, but not in all, the 
 creditor has, in addition, the right to demand specific performance, 
 and, in some cases, the judgment of the court will place him in the 
 same position as if the debtor had specifically performed the con- 
 tract. When, before the time for the performance arrives, one 
 party absolutely and definitely repudiates the contract, the other 
 party is entitled either to wait till the time of performance arrives 
 and then to bring his action, or he may at once treat the contract 
 as broken and sue for rescission of it and for damages. 
 
 So, for instance, in a contract of employment, if the employer 
 has wrongf ully dismissed the servant, the servant may please him- 
 self whether he will treat the contract as continuing and tender 
 his services, and sue for the wages as they would become payable, 
 or else, on the other hand, whether he will treat the contract as 
 definitely broken and demand immediate payment of a lump sum 
 for such damages as he can prove. (See Paris, 21 juin 1883, 
 D. 85. 2. 46; Agen, 23 nov. 1903, D. 1907. 2. 48.) 
 
 The various remedies are: — 
 
 (1) Rescission; 
 
 (2) Maintenance of contract partially executed, and damages 
 for inexecuted part; 
 
 (3) Substituted performance, or judgment having effect of per- 
 formance ; 
 
 (4) Specific performance; 
 
 (5) Damages. 
 
 These various remedies must be explained in more detail. 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 221 
 
 (1) The action for rescission or resolution of the contract. 
 
 It is a general rule that where there are reciprocal obligations 
 and one of the parties to the contract has performed or is willing 
 to perform his part, whereas the other party has failed to perform 
 his part, the first party may demand that the contract may be set 
 aside, and this without prejudice to his claim for damages. 
 (Planiol, 2. n. 1307.) 
 
 The tacit resolutory condition. 
 
 The traditional rule, ojLtlioJLarW -of- sale that if the price was not 
 paid within the stipulated delay the seller could sue for the dis- 
 solution of the sale was gradually extended in the French law to 
 all synallagmatic contracts. (Planiol, 2, n. 1310; Cassin, De 
 V exception tiree de Vmexecution, p. 162; Picard et Prudhomme, 
 De la resolution judiciaire pour inexecution des obligations, Rev. 
 Trim. 1912, p. 61.) 
 
 It is commonly spoken of as the tacit resolutory condition. 
 (C. C. F. 1184; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 901; Cassin, op. cit. 
 p. 94. See Req. 5 dec. 1906, D. 1907. 1. 249.) 
 
 The action for resolution of the contract is competent irre- 
 spective of the reasons which may have prevented the other party 
 from performance, and even though he was prevented by force 
 majeure. (Lyon, 10 mars 1908, S. 1910. 2. 49, and note by 
 M. Raynaud; Req. 19 oct. 1897, D. 97. 1. 576.) Nay more, 
 the partial inexecution of the contract, though it was caused by 
 force majeure, may justify the resolution of the contract at the 
 instance of the other party. (Cass. 26 juill. 1909, S. 1910. 
 1.71.) 
 
 Tho basis of the claim is the reciprocity of the obligations. 
 The one party performed his part on the implied condition that 
 the other party would make the counter-performance. Obviously, 
 the plaintiff must begin by showing that he is not to blame, that 
 he has done or is ready to do what he promised. He cannot be 
 allowed to break the contract and then to complain of the breach. 
 He is stopped or barred from (invoking his own non-execution of 
 the contract as a ground for its rescission. (Cassin, op. cit. 
 p. 739; Laurent, 17, n. 125; Cass. 26 juin 1912, D. 1914. 1. 
 307.) 
 
 But the court has power to rescind the contract although there 
 are faults on both sides. (Req. 22 dec. 1902, D. 1903. 1. 149. 
 Cf. Req. 31 dec. 1900, D. 1901. 1. 135.) 
 
222 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The Mixed Court of Appeal has expressed the rule thus: — 
 Le droit <i< resolution, quand il ng a pas de condition, resolu- 
 toire expresse, nest pas un droit absolu, mats subordowne a Vap- 
 precudion des cir Constance s ; lorsqu'il y a des torts reciproques 
 de la part de chacime des parties contractantes, cest aux tribunaux 
 de les peser et les circonstances peuvent etre telles que la resilia- 
 tion ne doive pas etre pronon-cee et qu'une condemnation a des 
 dommages-interets soit une reparation suffisante. (C. A. Alex. 
 3 fevr. 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 120. Cf. C. A. Alex. 31 mai 
 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 403.) 
 
 The exceptio non adimpleti contractus. 
 
 This is the name usually given to the defence that the plaintiff 
 in the action of resolution has not fulfilled his own part. The 
 exceptio non adimpleti contractus is implied. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 963.) 
 
 The defence has been thus defined in a recent work: L' exception 
 non adimpleti contractus est un mmjen de defense de bonne foi 
 offert a quiconque est oblige en mrtu d'un rapport synallagma- 
 tique sans etre tenu d'executer le premier, et qui consiste a refuser 
 la prestation due jusqua Vaccomplissement de la contre-pre sta- 
 tion incombant a V autre partie. (Bene Cassin, De V except ion 
 tiree de I 'inexecution, p. 440.) 
 
 So, the buyer of an article for a price payable at once cannot 
 enforce delivery without payment or tender of the price, for it 
 is a general rule that the party who claims specific performance 
 by the other must have first executed his part of the contract. 
 The one party cannot refuse to perform his obligation and treat 
 the contract as at an end until he has put the other party in 
 default. (Beq. ler dec. 1897, D. 98. 1. 289, and note by M. 
 Planiol.) But this will not be so when the circumstances show 
 that both parties had agreed to dissolve the contract. (Req. 5 
 nov. 1901, D. 1904. 1. 356; C. C. E. 279/350; C. C. F. 1612; 
 B.-L. et Saignat, Vente, n. 305. See, on the exceptio non adim- 
 pleti contractus in the German law, German Code, arts. 320—324; 
 Saleilles, Theorie Generate de V Oblig atirrn, 3rd ed. p. 187.) 
 
 Court has discretion to refuse resolution. 
 
 Even in a case where the plaintiff has not broken the contract 
 at all, and he demands its resolution on the ground of breach by 
 the defendant, the court is not bound independently of the eir- 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 223 
 
 cumsta noes to accede to the demand. Resolution cannot be 
 claimed: (1) unless the inexecution is definite, and (2) unless it 
 is of a serious nature. The action for resolution will be admitted 
 only, as a recent writer expresses it, lorsque I'inexecution totale 
 ou partielle des engagements aVune partie est sufjisamment grave 
 pour detruire cm detriment de I 'autre, Vequilibre de situation in- . 
 dispensable, ou pour rendre a, celle-ci impossible la realisation du 
 but poursuivi par elle en contractant. (Cassin, op. cit. p. 405. 
 See Cass. 18 avril 1904, S. 1904. 1. 144.) 
 
 It may be that the breach committed by the defendant is not 
 of very great importance, and the court may believe that even if 
 the plaintiff had foreseen the breach, he would still have entered 
 into the contract. It is by no means uncommon for a man who 
 is at first satisfied with his contract but afterwards becomes dis- 
 satisfied with it, to discover breaches of contract by the other 
 party which before then had not caused him any trouble. If 
 the court thinks the case is one of that kind it is entitled to refuse 
 the demand for resolution. As the Mixed Court expressed it, 
 la resolution d'un contrat ne doit pas etre necessairement or- 
 donnee pour toute inexecution, meme partielle, et quelle que soit 
 V importance des obligations assumees par les parties ; il appartient 
 au juge de decider d'apres les cir Constances, s'il y a ou non lieu a 
 resolution. (C. A. Alex. 1 avril 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 258.) 
 
 In that case resolution was demanded on the ground that the 
 vendor of an immoveable had not delivered the titles to the pur- 
 chaser. The purchaser had taken and occupied the property for 
 seven years and had suffered no inconvenience from the want of 
 the titles, and the vendor now offered to deliver them. There 
 had undoubtedly been a breach of the contract, but the court 
 held that it was not such a breach as to entitle the other party 
 to rescission. There is some difference of opinion in the French 
 doctrine with regard to the absolute right to demand rescission 
 in such a case, but the weight of authority is in the same sense 
 as the judgment just cited. If the prestation is divisible, and 
 there has been a partial prestation which has been of serious 
 advantage to the creditor, the court may maintain the contract 
 and order damages for the portion of the prestation which remains 
 unperformed. (Cass. 7 aout 1894, D. 95. 1. 108; Req. 15 fevr. 
 1904, D. 1904. 1. 335; Planiol, 2, n. 1321; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, 912; Req. 26 juill. 1909, D. 1911. 1. 55; Lyon, 10 
 mars 1908, D. 1909. 2. 33; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 137. See 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1184, nos. 27 seq.) 
 
224 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 According to another opinion, it is only in cases of partial 
 performance of an obligation not to do that the court has discre- 
 tion to refuse resolution. If the obligation is a positive one to do 
 or to transfer, and there has been a partial performance only, 
 the court has not any such power to refuse resolution. (Aubry 
 ct Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 126, and note 80. See note to Cass. 2 fevr. 
 1904, D. 1904. 1. 271; D. N. C. C. art. 1143, n. 36.) 
 
 But this distinction does not seem to be justified, and the ten- 
 dency of the jurisprudence is for the courts to claim a wider 
 discretion to accord or to refuse resolution according to the equities 
 of the particular case. (See the instances collected by MM. Picard 
 and Prudhomme in Rev. Trim. 1912, p. 61.) 
 
 (2) Maintenance of contract partially executed and damages 
 
 for inexecuted part. 
 
 When there has been a partial performance of the contract, the 
 creditor is not obliged to demand the rescission of the contract; 
 he may prefer to maintain the contract so far as it has been 
 performed, and to demand damages for the unperformed part. 
 
 For, it is clear that there is no reason to compel the creditor 
 to ask for the rescission of the contract if he would rather keep 
 what he has got and take damages for what he has not got. So, 
 by way of illustration, if a debtor has sold a collection of a hundred 
 ancient coins each of them different from any other, and before 
 delivery he has carelessly lost five of them which cannot be re- 
 placed, the creditor may prefer to keep the ninety-five coins which 
 he has got and ask for damages in respect of the failure to deliver 
 the other five. 
 
 And, as we have already seen, if the creditor exercises his option 
 of demanding the rescission of the contract, the court has, in some 
 cases at any rate, discretion to refuse this demand and to compel 
 him to take damages instead for the loss which he has sustained 
 by the partial non- performance. 
 
 (3) Substituted performance, (4) specific performance, and 
 
 (5) damages. 
 
 Want of precision of the codes. 
 
 The codes do not explain in a satisfactory manner the relation 
 between these various remedies, though the Egyptian codes are 
 not so misleadinsr as the French Code is. 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 225 
 
 The French Code says roundly: Toute obligation de fawe ou 
 de ne pas faire se resold en dommages et interets, en cas d'in- 
 execution de la part du debitew (art. 1142). 
 
 This, if taken literally, would mean that when the obligation 
 is to do or not to do, and the debtor fails for any reason to make 
 the performance, even though this should be merely because he 
 does not choose to do so, the creditor must always be satisfied 
 with damages. The article is no doubt qualified to some extent 
 by the two articles which follow, but the three articles taken 
 together do not state with sufficient clearness the fundamental 
 principle which governs the whole matter. It is not every obliga- 
 tion to do or not to do which the courts decline to enforce specifi- 
 cally. It is only when the obligation involves an act or an 
 abstention of a personal kind on the part of the debtor, — when 
 that which he owes is a fait personnel, — that the court will refuse 
 to enforce it literally. 
 
 Specific performance will be ordered unless this is physically 
 impossible or involves an invasion of personal freedom. 
 
 The true principle is that specific performance is the natural 
 and proper remedy, and that the court will compel the debtor to 
 do the very thing which he has promised unless there is a valid 
 reason against it. /One such valid reason will be, no doubt, that 
 physical performance of the contract has become impossible. If, 
 for instance, the debtor has bound himself to deliver a specific 
 thing and this thing has been irretrievably lost, a judgment order- 
 ing specific performance would be illusory. 
 
 But it is a different reason from this which the French legis- 
 lator had mainly in view, when he stated in terms which are 
 much too absolute, that specific performance of an obligation to 
 do or not to do will not be compelled. The legislator had in mind 
 the class of cases in which the promised performance was a per- 
 sonal act, the literal performance of which could hardly be brought 
 about by force to any useful purpose, and where, if force were 
 exerted, it would involve an invasion of the bodily freedom of the 
 debtor. The law is not so foolish as to allow a debtor to refuse- 
 to perform his obligation unless there is some substantial reason 
 for according him this freedom. But there are many cases where 
 if a debtor refuses to perform a fait personnel to which he has 
 bound himself, the creditor would have little to gain by a judg- 
 ment ordering specific performance. If, for instance, a painter 
 has contracted to paint a picture and he refuses to complete it, a 
 
 w.— vol. ir. 15 
 
226 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 judgment ordering him to be imprisoned until he finished his 
 picture would not be likely to produce a great work of art. 
 
 To compel manu militwi acts or abstentions of such a personal 
 kind as this is hardly practicable. 
 
 The general principle has been clearly formulated by the Mixed 
 Court of Appeal in a recent case: 
 
 L' execution directe est la regie pour toute espece a" obligations 
 aussi bien de faire que de donner, et cette regie ne regoit £ excep- 
 tion pour Irs obligations de fairs— en ce sens que Vinexecution se 
 resold en donvmages in I, 'rets— que lorsque I 'intervention personnelle 
 du debiteur est necessaire pour V execution : dans tons les autres 
 cas, le creancier a le droit de demander V execution directe si elle 
 est possible, comme tel est le cas lorsqu'il sagit, par exemple de 
 contraindre le debiteur a payer a un tiers le prix delegue d'une 
 vente, fait qui aura pour resultat d'entrainer le degrevement force 
 par ce tiers dhm immeuble a lui hypvtheque. (C. A. Alex. 17 
 fevr. 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, p. 162.) 
 
 But the tendency of the French jurisprudence is to go further 
 than formerly in the direction of compelling specific performance 
 of contracts where that is physically possible, and a satisfactory, 
 result can be thereby attained. It will be explained later that by 
 the method of imposing an astreinte, the French courts are often 
 able to put great pressure upon a debtor to induce him to make 
 a literal performance of his promise. The rules applied by the 
 courts in France and in Egypt in regard to substituted perform- 
 ance and specific performance will appear more clearly from the 
 illustrations which follow. (See on the subject generally, Aubry, 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, pp. 62 seq.: B.-L. et Barde, 1, nos. 432 seq.; : 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, pp. 16 seq.) 
 
 The following cases must be distinguished: — 
 
 (a) Obligation to pay or to deliver a specific thing. 
 
 Where the obligation is to pay a sum of money a judgment can 
 be obtained under which the property of the debtor can be seized 
 and sold to produce the money. When the obligation is to deliver 
 a determinate thing— a corps certain— the judgment ordering the 
 delivery will be enforced by the officers of the court if that be 
 possible, but if the thing cannot be found the only remedy will 
 be damages. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 434; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, n. 62.) 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 227 
 
 (b) Obligations to do or not to do: 
 
 (3) Substituted performance. 
 
 The rule is that actual performance by the debtor of an obliga- 
 tion to do or not to do cannot be enforced whenever the obligation 
 requires the personal intervention of the debtor. 
 
 But in many cases the obligation is one which can be per- 
 formed equally well by another person as by the debtdr, and 
 the creditor may prefer to have it performed at the debtor's 
 expense rather than to claim damages for the inexecution. The 
 code says he may obtain leave of the court to do this if the 
 circumstances of the case permit. (C. C. E. 117/173.) Iti 
 gives the choice to the creditor to ask the one remedy or the other. 
 
 This means that the court must decide whether according to 
 law or according to the intention of the parties it is essential that 
 the debtor shall perform in person that which he has promised. 
 If this is not the case, specific performance by another at the 
 expense of the debtor may be ordered. When this is feasible 
 and it is demanded by the creditor it is the view of many French 
 writers that the court is bound to grant a judgment to this effect. 
 The creditor is given the option. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, 
 n. 436; Demolombe, 24, n. 505; D. X. C. C. arts. 1143-1144, 
 n. 37.) 
 
 If he is satisfied with the substituted performance he has a 
 right to it. But he is in no way compelled to accept it. He can 
 always ask for dissolution of the contract and damages. But 
 according to another system, when the plaintiff demands this sub- 
 stituted performance the court has discretion to refuse this form 
 of remedy and to give damages instead, and this is the view 
 adopted by the jurisprudence. (Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 65; 
 Req. 18 juin 1883, D. 84. 5. 353; D. N. C. C. arts. 1143—1144, 
 ji. 28.) 
 
 Under the Egyptian Code the addition of the words " if the 
 circumstances of the case permit " seems intended to make it 
 clear that the court has full discretion. (C. C. E. 117/173.) 
 
 (c) Cases where judgment takes place of performance. 
 
 Further, there are certain cases in which the judgment of tho 
 court will be in itself equivalent to performance of the contract 
 by the debtor. This is so when the debtor has bound himself to 
 sign a deed and has not executed his promise. But it is only where 
 
 15 (2) 
 
228 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the contract requires no special form that the rule applies. In 
 accordance with these principles the Mixed Court of Appeal held 
 in one case that it is not every obligation to do which necessarily, 
 resolves itself into damages in the event of inexecution on tho 
 part of the debtor, for in puch obligations to do as are susceptible 
 of being executed without the participation and material con- 
 course of the debtor the creditor may be authorised to get the 
 obligation performed at the expense of the debtor. 
 
 Accordingly, when a third party had bound himself to guarantee 
 the repayment of a loan by obliging himself jointly and severally 
 with the borrower in an acte authentique it was held that the 
 lender could force the third party to execute his promise or in 
 default could demand that the judgment should be equivalent— 
 valoir acte de garantie et titre executoire a son encpntre. (C. A. 
 Alex. 15 nov. 1899, B. L. J. XII, 10.) 
 
 It is important to notice that the authentic form was not essen- 
 tial to make the contract of suretyship binding. {Infra, p. 234.) 
 
 Where a man has promised to sell property, but has not exe- 
 cuted a deed of sale, the judgment may order him to execute the 
 deed, and in default of his so doing, it may be declared that the 
 judgment itself shall be held to be equivalent to the deed of sale. 
 (C. C. F. 1589; C. C. Q. 1476; B.-L. et Saignat, Vente, n. 66; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1589, n. 41; C. A. Alex. 9 mai 1895, B.L.J. 
 VII, 268.) 
 
 In regard to a promise to sell, the Code of Quebec contains an 
 express provision to this effect. (C. C. Q. 1476.) This is in 
 accordance with the interpretation given by the French jurispru- 
 dence to the rule stated in the code as to la promesse de vente . 
 And, although there is no corresponding article in the Egyptian 
 Code, there is no doubt that the law is the same, and there is a 
 considerable body of jurisprudence in this sense. (C. A. Alex. 
 20 dec. 1894, B. L. J. VII, 56; C. A. Alex. 23 janv. 1896, 
 B. L. J. VIII, 99. See, as to the effect of a promise of sale 
 in a question with third parties, Table Decennale, 2, n. 4285.) 
 
 Tho same rule applies to a lease. When the lessee has under- 
 taken to sign a lease and refuses to do so, the lessor may bring an 
 action to have him condemned to sign the lease, and in default 
 of his so doing to have it ordered that the judgment of the court 
 shall serve as such lease. (B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 1, n. 43; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1709, n. 198.) 
 
 But this rule would not apply to such a case as the obligation 
 to grant a hypothec. The court could not issue a judgment order- 
 ing the defendant to grant a hypothec and declaring that, failing 
 

 REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 229 
 
 his doing so, the judgment should avail as a hypothec. The 
 reason is that a hypothec can only be granted by an acte aiithen- 
 tique, and this requires the personal act of the parties which cannot 
 be enforced. (B.-L. et de Loynes, Privileges et II//pofhrques, 
 2, n. 1407.) 
 
 And the same is the case where the obligation is to deliver an 
 indeterminate thing which requires to be made determinate by 
 the act of the debtor. 
 
 In this case the only remedy is by way of damages. 
 
 (4) When can specific performance be claimed? 
 
 In regard to obligations to do or not to do we must draw the 
 important distinction above stated. If the acl necessary can be 
 done by another as well as by the debtor, the obligation may be 
 specifically performed, and that whether the obligation is one of a 
 positive or of a negative character. 
 
 The creditor may get the thing done and charge the debtor 
 with the expense, or in some cases, it may be ordered to be done 
 by the officers of the court. For instance, a mason contracts with 
 me to build a wall. 
 
 If he refuses to do it, I can get it built by another mason and' 
 charge the debtor with the cost and with damages in addition, if 
 any. Or, if I choose, I can set aside the contract and sue the 
 debtor for damages. 
 
 So if a man has contracted with me not to build a wall and 
 has built it, I can get an order of the court authorising me to get 
 it pulled down at his expense, and I can claim, in addition, any 
 damages. See Req. 14 mars 1899, D. 99. 1. 445.) 
 
 Can creditor always insist on demolition? 
 
 When the creditor wishes to destroy works which have been 
 executed by the debtor contrary to his obligation, it is clear that 
 the creditor cannot take the law into his own hands and pull 
 down the works without any authorisation. 
 
 But if the creditor asks the -authorisation of the court to destroy 
 the works, and proves that they have been erected contrary to the 
 obligation, is the court bound to grant him the authorisation to 
 destroy them, or has it a discretion to refuse this remedy and to 
 give him damages instead if this appear to be the more equitable 
 solution? This is a disputed question in France. According to 
 some writers, the court has no discretion in the matter and must 
 
230 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 order the destruction of the building if the creditor claims this 
 remedy, although this may be to cause to the debtor a loss much 
 greater than the damages sustained by the creditor. 
 
 If the debtor suffers a serious loss it is due to his own fault, 
 and he must bear it. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 438.) 
 
 But, according to other writers, the court has a discretion to 
 refuse the remedy asked by the creditor and to give him damages 
 instead. (Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 4, p. 65.) 
 
 The French jurisprudence is in the sense of the second opinion. 
 It has been hold in many cases that the court ought to refuse to 
 order the destruction or alteration of buildings erected contrary 
 to contracts where this would involve a loss to the debtor dispro- 
 portionate to the prejudice caused to the creditor by the con- 
 struction not being in conformity with the contract. 
 
 Such questions are apt to occur in cases where a contractor has 
 erected a building which is not in accordance witli the plans and: 
 specifications. (Cass. 2 fevr. 1904, D. 1904. 1. 271; Req. 18 
 fevr. 1903, D. 1903. 1. 487; Req. 31 oct. 1906, D. 1907. 1. 
 135, and the note; Req. 23 mars 1909, D. 1910. 1. 343/, 
 
 Under the Egyptian Code it seems clear that the court has 
 complete discretion. The French Code says "the creditor has 
 the right to demand that that which has been done in breach of the 
 contract should be destroyed." (C. C. F. 1143.) And even 
 under these terms the courts hold that his right is not absolute. 
 
 But the Egyptian Code merely says, " The creditor may, if 
 the circumstances of the case permit, obtain an authority from the 
 court to undo," etc. (C. C. E. 117/173.) It would seem that 
 this leaves to the court full discretion in the matter. 
 
 Fait personnel cannot be specifically enforced. 
 
 If the obligation is to do something which can be done only 
 by the debtor in person the creditor cannot get him compelled to 
 do it. For example, I contract with a painter for a portrait, or 
 with an actor to perform at my theatre. In such cases where the 
 object of the contract is a fait personnel damages only and not 
 specific performance can be claimed. It is to these cases thaC 
 the maxim is applicable. Nemo potest cogi prcecise ad factum. 
 But, in some cases, as will be explained presently, though the 
 debtor is not compelled by force to perform his contract, consider- 
 able pressure may be put upon him by the imposition of an 
 astreinte. 
 
 In refusing to enforce a fait personnel our law follows the 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 231 
 
 Roman. So in a case against the celebrated painter Rosa 
 Bonheur, it was held that the artist could not be compelled to 
 complete a picture. (Paris, 4 juill. 1865, D. 65. 2. 201.) 
 
 And the same rule applies where the obligation is not to do 
 something. If an actor undertakes not to perform at any other 
 theatre but one during a certain period, and he attempts to break 
 his contract, he cannot be dragged off the stage by force, and an 
 order cannot be obtained to prevent his breaking the contract. 
 For, according to the view of the Roman law and the French law, 
 this would affect the liberty of the subject. (Laurent, 16, n. 198; 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 18; D. N. C. C. art. 1143-1144, n. 19.) 
 
 In a case in Quebec a celebrated hockey player had engaged 
 to play with a certain team for the season and had bound himself 
 not to play with any other team. 
 
 He broke his contract and an injunction was applied foi- to 
 prevent his continuing to play with the team which he preferred. 
 The court held such an injunction could not be granted. He was 
 only liable in damages. (Pitre v. L' Association Athletique, 
 1910, R. J. Q. 20 K.OB. 41.) 
 
 Illustrations of cases where specific performance of the 
 contract may be demanded. 
 
 It is only when the performance of the obligation requires the 
 personal act of the debtor that the creditor must content himself 
 with damages, subject, however, to what will be said later as to 
 the power of the court to pronounce an astreinte. Where a per- 
 sonal act has been promised substituted performance is excluded, 
 for the act of another will not produce the same result as the act 
 of the debtor. If A will not paint the picture which he has 
 promised, nobody else can paint it. A picture by another artist 
 might be as good, but it would not be the same thing, and to 
 compel A, manu miUtari, to paint the picture, even if the law 
 permitted it, would not be likely to produce a valuable result. 
 But, in every case, when the obligation can be executed by a 
 third party without the debtor being put under any personal 
 restraint so as to be an invasion of his individual liberty, the 
 creditor can ask for the specific performance of the obligation to 
 be enforced even manu militwi. (Hue, 7, n. 135; D. X. C. C. 
 art. 1142, n. 48.) 
 
 The obligation to deliver a corps certain can always bo spceifi- 
 
232 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 cally enforced unless a third party has acquired a real right to 
 the thing. 
 
 Whenever the debtor has bound himself to deliver a deter- 
 minate thing, and its delivery is physically possible, the debtor 
 cannot liberate himself from his contract by offering to pay the 
 value of the thing and the damages. The creditor has the right 
 to refuse this, and to force the debtor to make the actual delivery, 
 and the judgment which orders the debtor to do this can be 
 enforced manu militari. (Demolombe, 24, n. 399; Laurent, 16, 
 n. 194; Aubry et Kau, 5th ed. 4, p. 62; D. N. C. C. art. 1136, 
 n. 13.) 
 
 But a judgment ordering the debtor to make the actual delivery 
 cannot be obtained if, between the date of the contract and the 
 action, a third party has acquired a real right to the thing. These 
 rules are clearly stated in the Egyptian Code: When the obliga- 
 tion is to transfer a specific corporeal thing the creditor may have 
 himself put in possession thereof, provided such thing was owned 
 by the debtor at the time .when the obligation came into existence 
 or since that time, and provided that no third person has acquired 
 a real right over it. (C. C. E. 118/175.) When the contract 
 is a translatory contract its effect, as we have seen earlier, is to 
 make the creditor at once the legal owner of the thing, although 
 his right as owner to revindicate the thing is liable to be defeated, 
 if the thing was an immoveable, by a later grantee whose title is 
 registered before his, or if the thing was a moveable, if the later 
 grantee has obtained possession of it. But, unless a third party 
 has in this way a< quired a right which is protected by the law 1 , 
 the creditor in an obligation de donner can claim the thing as 
 owner by the real action en revendication, and the delivery can 
 I nforced if necessary mailu militari. 
 
 Specific performance of obligation to grant a servitude. 
 
 It is not necessary in order to entitle the plaintiff to specific 
 performance that he shall have become owner of the thing under 
 an obligation de donner. It is sufficient that the debtor had 
 bound himself by the contract to deliver the thing to the creditor. 
 Ii the debtor has bound himself to create a servitude, the creditor 
 can bring an action en revcndication and obtain specific perform- 
 ance. (Demolombe, 24, n. 400; D. N. C. C. art. 711, n. 103; 
 D. Rep. vo. Propriete, n. 661.) 
 
REMEDIES FOR liKKACH OF CONTRACT. 233 
 
 Specific performance of contract of lease of thing. 
 
 The lessee of a thing has merely a personal right, and if the 
 lessor is in default to deliver the thing, the lessee's claim to be put 
 in possession is not in virtue of his having any real right. (See 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 5, p. 287. ) Nevertheless, according to 
 the French law, if the lessor, having possession of the thing v 
 wrongfully refuses to deliver it, he can be condemned to specific 
 performance, and the judgment can be enforced manu militari. 
 (B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 1, n. 308; Laurent, 25, n. 102; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1719, nos. 45, 54.) 
 
 And, conversely, if at the end of the lease the lessee refuses 
 to give up the possession he can be compelled to do so manu 
 militari. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 439; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 62; D. N. C. C. art. 1142, n. 50.) 
 
 Specific performance of promise to grant deed. 
 
 As we have seen, where there has been a promise by a debtor 
 to execute a conveyance and he has not fulfilled his promise, the 
 creditor may ask the court to declare the existence of the contract. 
 Such a declaration in the judgment is equivalent to the convey- 
 ance, and may be registered as such where this is necessary ta 
 protect the creditor's right. If, for instance, a transferor has sold 
 actions nominatives, that is to say, shares which can be transferred 
 only by entry in the books of the company upon a declaration of 
 transfer signed by the transferor, and the transferor refuses to 
 sign the transfer, the transferee can obtain a judgment which will 
 do instead. "(Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 
 2, n. 605. See C. Com. F. art. 36; Thaller, Traite Elementaire 
 de Droit Commercial, n. 601.) 
 
 In previous cases personal intervention of debtor is not 
 
 necessary. 
 
 In all the previous cases the view of the law is that the contract 
 can be executed specifically without the personal intervention of 
 the debtor. If he is ordered to deliver a thing he is not bound to 
 hand it over personally; he can do this by another. The only 
 * restraint that is put upon him is that he is not to interfere with 
 the creditor's obtaining possession. He is not, in a word, com- 
 pelled to execute the contract but only to abandon his opposition 
 
234 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 to its execution. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 439; Meynial, 
 Revue Pratique de Droit Frangais, 56. p. 401.) 
 
 Cases where specific performance cannot be demanded. 
 
 All obligations de donner can be specifically enforced where that 
 is materially possible, and so can obligations de faire, unless the 
 compulsory execution is either physically impossible or would be 
 incompatible with the personal freedom of the debtor. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 433; D. N. C. C. art. 1142, n. 52.) 
 Obligations de faire include, as already explained, all obligations 
 to deliver which do not make the creditor the owner of the thing or 
 give him a real right in it. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4. p. 60, 
 note 3; supra, I, pp. 18, 19.) 
 
 Where the contract is to do something which requires the exer- 
 cise of technical skill or artistic power it would be impossible to 
 compel the actual performance in any profitable sense. But even 
 when this element is not present, the French courts hold that if 
 the personal intervention of the debtor is made indispensable to 
 the performance of the act the remedy of specific performance is 
 excluded . 
 
 The debtor who has promised to grant a hypothec cannot be 
 compelled to execute his promise because the personal presence 
 of the grantor is essential for the creation of the acte authentique* 
 and without this there can be no conventional hypothec. (B.-L. 
 et de Loynes, Privileges, 2, n. 1407. See, for some other illustra- 
 tions, article on Specific Performance in French Law, by M. S. 
 Amos, Law Quarterly Review, 1901, p. 372.) 
 
 Astreintes. 
 
 May the court order specific performance subject to payment 
 
 of a penalty? 
 
 In the case of the breach of an obligation to do or not to do the 
 creditor may, as we have seen, demand the resolution of the con- 
 tract with damages, or where the obligation has been partially 
 executed, he may accept partial execution pro tanto and claim . 
 damages for the part which has not been executed. And, in 
 certain circumstances, the creditor who prefers to have the con- 
 tract performed rather than to take damages may obtain authority 
 to execute it at the expense of the debtor or to destroy what the * 
 debtor has done contrary to the contract. (C. C. E. 117/173, 
 174.) 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 235 
 
 But these may not be the only remedies available The creditor 
 may be entitled to claim specific performance upon the principles 
 just explained. Or, if the case is one in which specific perform- 
 ance cannot be enforced directly, there may be a means of enforc- 
 ing such performance indirectly by putting pressure upon tin- 
 debtor. If the creditor prefers to have the contract specifically 
 performed by the debtor, can he ask for a judgment ordering the 
 debtor to perform it within a certain delay subject to the payment 
 of a sum fixed by the court in advance in the event of non- 
 execution? It is universally admitted in the French law that 
 within certain limits the courts have power to issue a judgment 
 in this form, and the penalty fixed beforehand in the event of 
 non-execution has acquired the technical name of an astreinte of 
 astreinte penale. 
 
 There is, however, a serious conflict between the doctrine and 
 the jurisprudence in regard to the limits of this power. (See 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 478; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 65; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 208; D. N. 0. C. art. 1149, n. 51, and art. 1351, 
 nos. 1740 seq. ; Dissertation by M. Glasson in note to D. 99. 1. 
 393; Rev. Trim. 1903, p. 5, art. by A. Esmein; Jacques Berryer. 
 Des Astreintes, These, Paris, 1903; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, 
 Traite de Procedure Civile, 3rd ed. 4, nos. 9 seq. ; Cass. 20 janv. 
 1913, D. 1913. 1. 357.) 
 
 When the court has before it the necessary elements for cal- 
 culating the amount of damages which will be caused to the 
 plaintiff by the delay, the judgment may order the defendant to 
 pay a certain sum for each day or week, or other unit of time 
 during which the delay continues, unless he prefers to execute 
 his obligation. Or the court may, if it prefers to do so, order 
 the payment of a lump sum by way of damages if performance is 
 not made within the delay. 
 
 So long as the judgment is confined within these limits it is 
 fully covered by the discretionary power of the court to estimate 
 the damages. (Demolombe, 24, n. 495 ; B.-L . et Barde, 1, n. 477; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 64, and note 12; D. N. O. C. art. 
 1149,n. 52.) 
 
 But this is, according to the jurisprudence, subject to two 
 conditions: — 
 
 (1) That the execution of the obligation is still possible. For 
 if it is no longer possible, a judgment ordering the debtor to 
 perform it would be futile, and there is no reason why the damages 
 should not be ascertained at once. (Cass. 11 mai 1898, D. 99. 
 1. 310.) 
 
236 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 2) That there has not been a definite and final breach, of the 
 contract, for the theory of astreintes is only applicable to the case 
 of delay in the execution and not to non-performance in the 
 proper sense. (Donai, 9 juill. 1906; Rev. Trim. 1906, p. 910; 
 Req. 26 juill. 1804, D. 54. 1. 297. See, however, Req. 25 mars 
 1857, D. 57. 1. 213.) 
 
 And, according to many writers, we must add a third condition, 
 viz.: — 
 
 (3) That if the obligation is one the execution of which re- 
 quires the personal act of the debtor, he can always claim that 
 the effect of the judgment fixing damages at so much a day shall be 
 stayed, by declaring that he cannot or will not execute the obliga- 
 tion and by demanding that a definite sum shall be fixed for the 
 damages. (Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 67; Demolombe, 24, 
 n. 497; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, Traite de Procedure Civile, 3rd 
 ed. 4, n. 8.) But, as we shall see, this opinion is contrary to that 
 generally adopted by the French courts. 
 
 Extension by the jurisprudence of the principle of astreintes. 
 
 The French jurisprudence has greatly extended the principle of 
 astreintes. Within the limits above indicated we may say that 
 the court does not fix a penalty, but merely ascertains beforehand 
 what the damages would have been in the event of non-perform- 
 ance, and gives the debtor the choice of executing the obligation 
 specifically, or of paying the damages so ascertained. 
 
 In the latter case, theoretically, at any rate, he is not called 
 upon to do more than to make reparation for the prejudice which 
 he has caused to the creditor. It is true that the amount of the 
 prejudice may be liberally estimated by the court, but this is 
 within its discretion. But if a debtor can be ordered to make 
 execution where that is possible, subject to payment of damages if 
 he refuses or fails to do so, why should the court not fix the 
 damages at such an amount as may be sufficient to overcome the 
 resistance, although this amount may be disproportionate to the 
 loss actually caused to the creditor? In other words, may the 
 fixing of an astreinte be employed by the courts as a. threat to 
 overcome the resistance of a recalcitrant debtor? 
 
 The astreinte will then be more than damages, it will be a 
 veritable penalty. And, further, if the court fixes such a penalty 
 and the debtor, even after the delay, performs his obligation, or 
 makes a partial performance of it, is the penalty fixed by the 
 judgment definite and irrevocable, or has the court power to modify 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 237 
 
 it ? Upon these points there is a large and not entirely consistent 
 body of jurisprudence in France. (See D. 91. 1. 31, and the 
 note; Req. 6 fevr. 1900, D. 1900. 1. 167: and for a list of the 
 hading cases, Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 66; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1149, n. 63.) 
 
 In this extended sense, the astreinte is not properly an allocation 
 of damages, it is an indirect method of compelling an obstinate 
 debtor to fulfil his obligation. The only damages of winch the 
 code speaks are damages which consist in the amount of the loss 
 sustained by the creditor and of the gain which he has failed to. 
 make. (O. C. E. 121/179.) 
 
 But, according to the French jurisprudence, an astreinte may 
 be pronounced even when no prejudice results to the creditor 
 from the delay. (Req. 6 avril 1900, D. 1900. 1. 167.) 
 
 And, where an actual prejudice has been sustained, the astreinte 
 may be out of all proportion to this prejudice. Moreover, when 
 the court has liquidated the damages for the non-performance of 
 an obligation, and has pronounced a judgment for the amount, 
 this is chose jugee, and the court has no power afterwards to alter 
 the amount of damages so fixed. 
 
 Whereas, in the case of the astreinte, it is the settled juris- 
 prudence in France that the court may afterwards reduce the 
 amount or may even relieve the debtor from the penalty altogether. 
 (Cass. 25 nov. 1884, D. 85. 1. 399; Req. 7 nov. 1888, D. 89. 1. 
 259; Toulouse, 30 juin 1909. S. 1909. 2. 272; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1149, n. 71; Sirey, Table DeCennale, 1901—1910, vo. Dom- 
 ■mages-lnterets, n. 66.) 
 
 It is, therefore, with good reason that M. Planiol places his 
 discussion of astreintes not under the head of damages, but under 
 the head of execution forcee, as one of the' means of compelling 
 the execution of an obligation. '2, n. 210.) Damages in the 
 proper and legal sense are paid not to compel performance, but 
 to compensate the creditor for the loss he has suffered by the 
 non-performance . 
 
 The astreinte, on the other hand, is the threat of a penalty to 
 induce execution. In its extended sense it is always oomminatory 
 and provisional, whereas damages are neither the one nor the 
 other. The astreinte is well defined by M. Berryer: — 
 
 On appelle astreinte une condemnation pecuniaire ai/anf an 
 caractere provisoire, destinee a.obtenir indirectement I'execution 
 en nature d'une obligation, par la menace d'une peine susceptible 
 
238 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 de vaincre la resistance du debiteur. (Des Astreintes, These, 
 Paris, 1903, p. 20.) 
 
 According to the French jurisprudence, the courts may pro- 
 nounce a judgment ordering damages at the rate of so much a day 
 for delay in execution, intending this judgment to be a final 
 liquidation of the damages, and, if this is the intention, there can 
 be no subsequent revision of the amount fixed by the court which 
 has pronounced the judgment; the judgment is chose jugee. 
 
 On the other hand, the astreinte may be intended to be eom- 
 minatory, in which case it is subject to revision, and it is a pure 
 question of interpretation whether the judgment falls in the one 
 class or the other. Req. 7 nov. 1888, D. 89. 1. 259. See 
 Req. 3 fevr. 1909, D. 1909. 1. 120.) 
 
 Illustrations from the jurisprudence. 
 
 The method of attempting to overcome the resistance of the 
 debtor by an astreinte has been frequently employed when the 
 debtor has got possession of a document and refuses to produce it. 
 (Cass. 28 dec. 1824, S. 25. 1. 65; Journal du Palais, 1824, 
 p. 1269.) 
 
 Or, again, when one of the consorts has been ordered by a 
 judgment to give to the other consort the custody of the children 
 of the marriage. For example, in the famous Banff remont case, 
 the wife was ordered to give up the children subject to an astreinte 
 of 500 francs a day, which was afterwards raised to 1,000 francs 
 a day, and under this order the Princesse de Bauff remont incurred 
 a liability of more than a million francs. Paris, 7 aout 1876, 
 D. 78. 2. 125. See Paris, 4 janv. 1876, D. 78. 2. 68; and Cass, 
 de Belgique, 19 janv. 1882, D. 82. 2. 81.) Such cases of im- 
 posing heavy astreintes to enforce obedience to orders of the court 
 as to the custody of children are less likely to occur in future in 
 France, as by the Loi du 5 dec. 1901, refusal to obey such an order 
 is made a delict, and article 357 of the Code Penal is amended in 
 that sense. ;See for an account of this Loi, Berryer, op. cit. 
 p. 320.; 
 
 Tb.3 greater part of the French decisions imposing astreintes 
 have probably been pronounced in cases of this last class where 
 the debtor was in default to perform a duty arising from the law, 
 such as one of the reciprocal duties between husband and wife, 
 or parent and child, and it has been suggested that the method 
 is particularly appropriate to such cases, because for the breach of 
 
REMEDIES EOR BREACH OE CONTRACT. 239 
 
 such duties it is not possible to fix damages in money which shall 
 really be equivalent. 
 
 It is i n the public inj tcivst that such_jiufae«-&hG-ukL_b e specifically 
 performed. See Esmein, Rev. Trim. 1903, p. 21, for a criti- 
 cism of this argument, and B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 478.) But 
 the French courts have by no means confined astreintes to such 
 cases. They have applied an astreinte to enforce obligations to 
 do and_obli ffations notJ o__dp_ even when flwTact which was the 
 object of the obligation was an act of a personal kind. For 
 instance, the Tribunal de la Seine condemned Mile. Rachel, the 
 actress, to pay 200 francs a day so long as she refused to play a 
 role in a certain play, this refusal being contrary to the terms of 
 her engagement with Legouve, the author. (Trib. Seine, 21 oct. 
 1854, D. 54. 3. 80.) 
 
 And in the affaire Coquelin, the Court of Appeal of Paris con- 
 firmed a judgment condemning Coquelin to, pay 500 francs a day 
 up to thirty days for every contravention of his engagement not 
 to appear on any stage except that of the Comedie Franchise. 
 After thirty days the court was to take up the question anew. 
 (Paris, 21 avril 1896, D. 97. 2. 177. Cf. Cass. 8 janv. 1901, 
 D. 1901. 1. 277.) And the principle that the astreinte may be 
 comminatory is excellently illustrated in the case where an electric- 
 light company which had contracted to supply electric-light to 
 an hotel in Paris, and refused! to fulfil its contract, was condemned 
 to pay 100 francs a day, a sum which was raised afterwards to 
 10,000 francs a day, till it supplied the light. (Cass. 1 dec. 1897, 
 D.98. 1.289.) 
 
 But when a contract is in its nature terminable at the will of 
 eitherjaarty, such as the contract, of lease of services when no 
 ,/triod is fixed, the court will not employ the method of astreintes 
 to compel the employer to take back the employee. 
 
 In the French law the unjustifiable dismissal of the employee 
 gives him a right to damages, but it does not give him a right to 
 be reinstated in the employment. (Civ. 18 juill. 1916, D. 1916. 
 1.286.) 
 
 A question which has been much disputed is whether when there 
 is an appeal from a judgment imposing an astreinte and the judg- 
 ment is confirmed, the astreinte should run from the date of the 
 first judgment, or from the date of the judgment by the Court of 
 Appeal. According to the view of the Cour de Cassation, when 
 the judgment of the Court below is confirmed, the position is the 
 
240 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 same as if the parties had accepted the first judgment as final. 
 (Cass. 15 nov. 1881, D. 82. 1. 134.) 
 
 But most of the French courts of appeal and of the courts of 
 first instance do not accept this view. They argue that the party 
 who appeals makes use in so doing of a right given to him by the 
 law. He cannot determine the length of time which will be 
 occupied before his case is decided on appeal, and he ought not to 
 be penalised by being made to pay so much a day during a delay 
 to which he is entitled. Upon this theory the astreinte should run 
 only from the date of the second judgment. (Trib. de Sens, 15 
 juill. 1909, D. 1911. 2. 303; Paris, 12 fevr. 1908, D. 1909. 2. 
 113, and the note; Eev. Trim. 1911, p. 800.) This second theory 
 appears to be preferable to that of the Oour de Cassation. It has 
 been adopted in Egypt by the Court of Appeal of the Mixed 
 Courts and by the Native Court of Appeal. C. A. Alex. 16 
 janv. 1879, R. O. IV, 97; C. A. 22 janv. 1907, O. B. VIII, 
 n. 77, p. 58.) 
 
 According to the French jurisprudence, where the astreinte is 
 purely comminatory, it can be modified afterwards by the court 
 which pronounced it if the case comes again before this court for 
 final determination. (Montpellier, 1 avril 1862, D. 62. 5. 112; 
 Bordeaux, 5 mai 1870, D. 70. 2. 208; Req. 8 nov. 1864, D. 65. 
 
 1. 389; C. A. Alex. 16 janv. 1879, R. O. IV, 97.) 
 
 In one case the Court of Paris expressed the opinion that the 
 court of first instance which had pronounced an astreinte had no 
 power to vary the amount though a court of appeal might do so. 
 (Cass. 1 dec. 1897, D. 98. 1. 289. See C. A. 22 janv. 1907, 
 O. B. VIII, n. 77, p. 58.) 
 
 This opinion is supported in the note to the case by M. Planiol. 
 It is submitted, however, that it is not sound. If the judgment 
 fixing the astreinte was intended to be a liquidation of the 
 damages it will be final and not subject to any reduction. But if 
 the judgment is purely comminatory it is not chose jugee, but 
 is of a provisional character, and the question whether the judg- 
 ment is of this kind or not is a question of interpretation. (Req. 
 9 janv. 1889, D. 91. 1. 128; Toulouse, 30 juin 1909, S. 1909. 
 
 2. 272; D. N. C. C. art. 1351, n. 1756; Observations du ccm- 
 sciller -rapporteur, in Cass. 7 nov. 1888, D. 89. 1. 261. See 
 C. A. Alex. 16 janv. 1879, R. O. IV, 97.) 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 241 
 
 Criticism of the jurisprudence. 
 
 The French doctrine with few dissentient voices rejects alto- 
 gether the comminatory astreintes. It is argued that the courts 
 have no power to fix penalties arbitrarily. II nest pas de peine 
 sans texte. Further, it is said that no court can alter a judgment 
 it has once pronounced. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 479; 
 Dissertation of M. Glasson, in note to Cass. 5 juill. 1898, D. 99. 
 1.393.) 
 
 The best defence of the legality of astreintes is that by M. 
 Esmein. His argument is that we must distinguish between judg- 
 ments and injunctions or orders of the court, between judicia 
 ordinatoria and judicia decisoria, a distinction made by the Cour 
 de Cassation in an arret of 22 nov. 1841 . (S. 42. 1 . 170; Journal 
 du Palais, 1842, tome 1, p. 322.) The astreinte is an order by 
 the court, compliance with which is enforced by a threat. If and 
 when the order has been executed to the satisfaction of the judge 
 he withdraws the threat. 
 
 He may, according to his discretion, reduce the amount payable 
 even if the order made by the judgment has not been complied 
 with. .Every judge who is seized with a suit has power to issue- 
 orders connected with the suit and to enforce compliance with 
 them. In issuing such an order he is not exercising his juris- 
 diction, but his imperium or power of making a command. 
 This power has been recognised in France at all times and was not 
 taken away by the codes. (See Heinrion de Pansey, de V 'Autorite 
 Judiciaire, These, Paris, 1910, p. 101.) Article 1036 of the 
 French Code of Procedure as a recognition of this power. (Rev. 
 Trim. 1903, p. 5.) And M. Esmein's view is accepted by M. 
 Planiol (2, nos. 208 seq.). 
 
 Astreintes in Egyptian jurisprudence. 
 
 In Egypt, in spite of the criticism of the French writers, the 
 legality of astreintes does not seem to have been called in question. 
 The Egyptian courts have not hesitated to follow the French 
 jurisprudence, and to condemn a recalcitrant debtor to pay the 
 plaintiff a fixed sum for every day's delay, and, as in France, 
 it is considered a question of interpretation whether the sum' bo 
 fixed is intended to stand in place of damages or to be purely corn- 
 minatory. When the judgment contains no clause of execution — 
 titre executoire — it will certainly be regarded as merely commina- 
 
 w.— VOL. ii. 16 
 
242 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 tory . This has been held to be the case where the Nazir of a Wakf 
 was ordered to render an account and to pay two pounds for each 
 day's delay; where a defendant had violently seized land belong- 
 ing to the plaintiff and had been condemned to pay a sum by way 
 of damages, and also P. T. 500 for each day's delay in returning 
 the land; and also where a defendant was ordered to deliver goods 
 and to pay ten pounds a day during the delay. (Native Court of 
 Appeal, 12 janv. 1904, Al Hocouk, XX, p. 133; C. A. 16 janv. 
 1879, R O. IV, 97; C. A. 10 janv. 1901, R. O. XXIV, 130. Cf. 
 Trib. Zagazig, 4 fevr. 1909, O. B. X, n. 90.) 
 
 The Mixed Court of Appeal recently declined to impose an 
 astreinte to enforce payment of a sum of money, and observed that 
 an astreinte ne pent etre> en tout cas decretee que quand elle est 
 destinee a obtenir du debiteur V execution d'une obligation clef aire. 
 (C. A. Alex. 3 avrill913, B.L. J. XXV, 286.) 
 
 Judgments imposing astreintes have become common form in 
 actions demanding the rendering of accounts. Where an astreinte 
 has been imposed, and the case has been carried to appeal, the 
 Egyptian courts have held that the appeal suspends the astreinte, 
 contrary to the jurisprudence of the Cour de Cassation which has 
 been referred to above. (C. A. 22 janv. 1907, O. B. VIII, n. 77, 
 p. 58; C. A. 16 janv. 1879, R. O. IV, 97.) 
 
 Both the Native and the Mixed Courts have found no diffi- 
 culty in considering astreintes as purely comminatory, leaving to 
 the court the power to revise the judgment afterwards, and to 
 modify the astreinte, and even to relieve the defendant altogether 
 from the payment of it if he had a legitimate excuse for the inexe- 
 cution. La condemnation a des dommages-interets a raison de 
 tant par jour de retard dans I'executian nest definitive que s'il 
 est possible an juge de determiner le dommage reel et exact qui 
 resulterait du retard . 
 
 horsquelle ria que le car act ere d'une tnesure coercitive destinee 
 a assurer Vexecution de la decision, pareii'te condemnation estpure- 
 ment comminatoire et pent etre modifiee ulterieurement. (C. A. 
 11 jum 1917, O. B. XVIII, n. 114, p. 69; also Mixed Court; 
 C. A. Alex. 12 dec. 1895, B. L. J. VIII, 39; Native Court of 
 Appeal, 12 janv. 1904, Review El-Mahakem, 16, p. 3481; C. A. 
 16 janv. 1879, R. O. IV, 97; C. A. 10 janv. 1901, R. O. XXVI, 
 130.) 
 
 In the last case the principle is clearly stated que par la con- 
 damnation precitee les premiers juges n'ont pas adjuge des dom- 
 mages-interets deja acquis, ou tout an moins des dommages- 
 
REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 24-3 
 
 interets futurs, proportionnes a un prejudice a encourir, qu'ih 
 n'ont fait qu'edicter une peine en rac de donner sanction a leur 
 decision usant de la menace d'une condantnation comme d'un 
 moyen de contrainte. 
 
 But the Egyptian courts have sometimes failed to carry the 
 principle to its logical conclusion by refusing to enforce the penaltjy 
 even though the debtor remained recalcitrant, and holding that 
 the plaintiff could recover only the actual damage suffered. Que 
 les condemnations de cette sorte ne sont que purement com'mina- 
 ioires, et quelles ne peuveuf sortir a effet que dans la memrr du 
 prejudice reellement smffert. (C. A. 10 janv. 1901, R. O. XXVI, 
 130; Trib. Ap. Ind. Caire, 8 mai 1906, O. B. VII, n. 115, p. 79.) 
 
 It is submitted that this view of the matter is erroneous. The 
 court has power to modify the amount of the astreintes, but it has 
 also power to overcome the resistance of the defendant by making 
 him pay a larger sum than the loss which he has actually caused to 
 the plaintiff. A threat which can never be enforced is a bra lam 
 fulmen and not likely to be very efficacious. 
 
 Enforcement of specific performance in other laws. 
 
 In Belgium, the courts after some hesitation have accepted the 
 system ,of astreintes as developed by the French jurisprudence. 
 (Gand, 22 juin, 1907, Pasicrisie, 1909, 1, 309; Rev. Trim. 1911, 
 p. 201; C. Cass, de Belgique, 23 juin 1887, D. 88. 2. 311. 
 Contra, Cass, de Belgique, 19 janv. 1882, D. 82. 2. 81.) 
 
 In England, specific performance is enforced in appropriate 
 v cases by a judgment ordering specific performance or by an injunc- 
 tion, disobedience in either case rendering the defendant liable 
 to imprisonment. (See Halsbury, Laws of Eng. s. v. Injunction, 
 Specific performance . ) 
 
 In Germany, the matter is regulated by the new Code of Proce- 
 dure. (Civil Prozessordnung, arts. 887,888.) If the act promised 
 can be done by a third party the creditor has the right to a judg- 
 ment authorising him to get it done at the debtor's expense. If 
 it cannot be done by the third party the court may condemn the 
 debtor to fines up to the amount of 1,500 marks, and even to 
 imprisonment; and the creditor may recover damages in addition. 
 
 16 (2) 
 
244 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XIII. 
 
 DAMAGES FOR BREACH OE A PECUNIARY OBLIGATION. 
 
 This matter is thus dealt with in the Egyptian Native Code: 
 When the object of an obligation is the payment of a sum of 
 money, interest is due thmeon, but only from the day on- which 
 legal 'proceedings are commenced., unless in particular cases the 
 agreement, commercial custom, or the law provides otherwise. 
 
 Subject to any agreement $o the contrary, the rate of interest 
 shall be five per cent, 'in civil causes, and seven per cent, in com- 
 mercial causes. 
 
 The interest fixed by agreement may never exceed nine per 
 oent. Compound interest may never be charged or claimed upon 
 less than one year's interest. 
 
 Nevertheless, the rate of commercial interest upon current 
 accounts may vary accordiaig to the rate on Exchange, and the 
 interest shall be capitalized in such current accounts in accordance 
 with commercial custom. (C. 'C. N. 124—127.) The Mixed 
 Code is the same in effect . (C . C . M . 182— 187 .) 
 
 These articles 'are based upon the French Code. (C. C. F. 
 1153.) They lay down three rules: — 
 
 (1) The rule that interest is due from the commencement of 
 legal proceedings. This creates an exception to the rule that 
 damages are due from a mise en demeure. Instead of a mise en 
 demeure, in this case, the Egyptian law requires a demande en 
 justice. 
 
 The French Code was to the same effect until it was amended 
 by the hoi du 7 avril 1900. As the French Code now stands, 
 interest runs from the date of a demand by the creditor — somma- 
 tion de payer. The reason why the old law required a demande en 
 justice in this case and not in others is not very clear. Demolombe 
 said it was because the law desires in the interest of the debtor 
 that the creditor should manifest categorically and energetically 
 his determination to cause interest to run; categorically, that is 
 IWf- 
 
DAMAGES FOR BREACH OF A PECUNIARY OBLIGATION. 245 
 
 in clear unequivocal language; energetically, that is to say by a 
 document so threatening as to leave the debtor no illusions. (24, 
 n. 625.) But, as Laurent says, why should the debtor be under 
 any illusion, if the creditor, instead of bringing an action, makes a 
 clear and definite extra-judicial demand? (16, n. 319.) 
 
 Probably, as Hue says, the rule is a survival of the disfavour 
 attaching to usury on account of the facility with which the accu- 
 mulation of interest increases the debt. (7, n. 156; B.-L. et 
 Baa-de, Oblig. 1, n. 511.) 
 
 The retention of the rule that the demande en justice is neces- 
 sary is explicable in Egypt upon religious grounds. The taking 
 of interest is contrary to the religious belief of Mohammedans, 
 and it is, therefore, not unreasonable that if money has been lent 
 without interest, and the lender wishes to claim interest when 
 payment is not made at the time agreed upon, he should be obliged 
 to declare this determination in a very formal manner. 
 
 The dies a quo from which the interest is to be calculated is 
 that of the service of a writ of summons. (Cass. 8 juillet 1907, 
 D. 1908Trf452 ; Cass. 21 juill. 1909, D. 1910. 1. 25.) 
 
 The court is without power to grant damages by way of interest 
 on a money-debt from any earlier period than that of the demande 
 en justice unless there is an agreement to the contrary or the 
 case is one in which interest runs de plein droit. These cases' 
 are referred to later. (See Cass. 21 dec. 1909, D. 1911. 1. 316.) 
 ( w 2) The damages are to consist always of the interest on the 
 money due. They are moratory damages and not compensatory 
 damages ; it is simply the delay in payment which creates the 
 liability. 
 
 (3) The creditor does not need to prove that he has suffered 
 prejudice. The French Code says expressly ces dommages et 
 interets srnit dus sums quch cremcier soit- term de justifier d-cmcuma 
 perte. (C. C. F. 1153.) The Egyptian Code says simply 
 les interets sont dus. (C. C. E. 124.) 
 
 But this is sufficient, because the code does not say that any 
 prejudice must have been suffered before the interest can run. 
 The reason for this difference between money-debts and others 
 is doubtless that a person who counts upon getting his money at 
 a certain date may reasonably be presumed to suffer prejudice if 
 it is not duly paid. Under modern conditions, it is taken for 
 granted that the creditor would not have allowed his money to 
 remain idle. On the other hand, it would be difficult for the 
 creditor to prove what use he would have made of the money if 
 
 fcJW A*" 
 
 . W4 JU Wv WW 
 
246 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 it had been paid when it was due. It is to cut short all inquiries 
 of this kind that the law says the damages shall be assumed to 
 be the interest at the legal rate unless there is an agreement to 
 the contrary. (See Cass. 10 juill. 1895, D. 96. 1. 119.) 
 
 When damages are sought merely for delay in the payment of a 
 money-debt it is not competent to award the creditor damages 
 over and above the lawful interest on the ground that being 
 deprived of his money has caused him special damage, except only 
 in the case of bad faith. (Cass. 30 juin 1898, 2e. espece, D. 
 1900. 2. 300.) And, on the other hand, the court has no power 
 to refuse the creditor the legal interest from the demand, what- 
 ever may have been the original character of the debt, if its 
 execution consists in the payment of a sum of money. (Cass. 
 10 juill. 1894, D. 96. 1. 119.) 
 
 Special damage in case of bad faith. 
 
 According to a settled jurisprudence in France, if the creditor 
 could show that in consequence of the bad faith of the debtor 
 in not paying his debts he had suffered a prejudice over and 
 above that resulting from delay, he was entitled to recover separate 
 damages upon this head. They were not damages for delay in 
 payment but for the fault of the debtor. 
 
 And it was agreed by the French writers that this jurisprudence 
 was consistent with art. 1153. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, 
 n. 507; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 177, and note 50, ter ; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 270; 1 Req. 15 mars 1881, D. 81. 1. 368, note 2; 
 Cass. 3 mai 1897, S. 97. 1. 319; Cass. 23 nov. 1903, D. 1906. 1. 
 64.) 
 
 By the amendment made by the Loi du 7 avril 1900 to art. 1153 
 of the French Code a clause was added stating the law in the 
 sense of the jurisprudence. Le crea.ncier auquel son debiteitr en 
 retard a came par sa mauvaise foi, un prejudice independent de 
 ce retard, pent obtenir des dommages-interets distincts des interets 
 momtoircs de la creance. (See Cass. 14 fevr. 1911, D. 1911. 
 1. 216.) This addition to the code merely declared the existing 
 law in France, and the Egyptian law is the same. 
 
 German and Swiss laws as to this. 
 
 The German Code goes somewhat further. But this may be 
 partly because the legal rate of interest is only four per cent. 
 The creditor is allowed to claim damages in excess of the interest 
 
 
DAMAGES FOR BREACH OF A PECUNIARY OBLIGATION. 217 
 
 on the money if he can show that ho has suffered prejudice by the 
 delay, and he does not need to prove fault or bad faith on the 
 part of the debtor (art. 288). 
 
 It would be sufficient, for instance, if he showed that by the 
 delay he had lost the opportunity of a good investment at six 
 per cent., in which case the debtor would be bound to pay the 
 difference between four and six per cent, during the delay. 
 (Cosack, Lehrbuch des Deutschen burgerlichen Rechts, 6th ed. 1, 
 p. 423.) The Swiss Federal Code of Obligations also makes 
 the debtor liable to pay supplementary damages if any have been 
 caused, unless he proves that the delay was without his fault 
 (art. 106). 
 
 Exceptions to rule that only legal interest is due. 
 
 The French Code says the rule that damages for delay in 
 payment of an obligation of this kind consist only of the 
 legal interest is sanf les regies particulieres cm commerce et 
 cm cauticmnement . (C. C. F. 1153.) The Egyptian Code is 
 silent upon this point but elsewhere two exceptions to the rule 
 are stated. The recognised exceptions in the French law are: 
 
 (1) The right of the surety who has paid the debt to recover 
 from the principal debtor not only the amount which he has paid 
 and the interest from the date of payment, but also any damages 
 which he may have sustained. (C. C. F. 2028. Cf. C. C. E. 
 505/617.) 
 
 It is somewhat surprising that the Egyptian Code should 
 abandon the traditional principle of the French law that a surety 
 who has rendered a service in this way is entitled to complete 
 reimbursement as having acted in the character of a mandatary. 
 (Planiol, 2, n. 2356; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 501; D. X. C. C. 
 art. 1153, n. 21.) 
 
 But in a matter of this kind, the courts are bound to give a 
 strict interpretation to the code. If there were any doubt as to 
 what the code meant it would be interpreted in favour of the 
 debtor. We must, therefore, conclude that in the Egyptian law 
 the surety can claim only what he has paid and the interest upon 
 this amount. (Grandmoulin, SiireUs Personnelles, p. 16; Halton, 
 1, p. 275.) 
 
 (2) A partner who fails to pay his contribution to the assets 
 of the firm— his apport — is liable to pay damages as well as interest 
 for the delay. (C. C. F. 1816; C. C. E. 426/518.) 
 
<248 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (3) When a bill of exchange is not paid at maturity the holder 
 may by means of a cross-bill— retraite— recover from the drawer 
 or one of the indorsers not only the principal amount of the bill 
 and the legal interest but also the cost of the re-exchange. 
 C. Cm,,,. F. 177 -186; C. Com. E. 180/187.) 
 
 Compound interest. 
 
 The compounding or capitalization of interest— anatoclsme— 
 has always been regarded by the law with great suspicion. The 
 agreement by the debtor that instead of paying the interest on his 
 debt the interest shall be added to the capital is dangerous to 
 society for two reasons: — 
 
 (a) It is extremely tempting to an impecunious man because 
 he ^ets his money in this way for the time being without having 
 to pay anything for it. 
 
 (b) It leads to an increase in the principal debt much greater 
 than the debtor is likely to have anticipated. Money lent at five 
 per cent, doubles in about fourteen years. But this fact is as a 
 rule much more clearly present to the mind of the money-lender 
 than it is to that of the borrower. For these reasons, the com- 
 pounding of interest was absolutely forbidden in the later Roman 
 law. 'C. 4. 32. 28.) The prohibition was maintained in the 
 old French law as a part of the policy of preventing usury. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 525; Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 4, p. 180.) It 
 is forbidden also by the German Code (art. 289), and by the Swiss 
 Code of Obligations (art. 314). 
 
 It is, however, allowed by the French and Egyptian codes 
 subject to certain conditions. (C. C. F. 1154; C. C. E. 
 126, 127 186, 187.) 
 
 1 By the Egyptian codes the capitalization or adding of the 
 interest to the principal is to be made only at the end of each 
 year, except in the case of current accounts. (2) In regard to 
 current accounts— comptes couremts — the capitalization may be 
 made according to commercial custom. The nature and the legal 
 effect of current accounts are matters which belong to the com- 
 mercial law. (See Thaller, Tralte Elementair e de Droit Com- 
 mercial, nos. 1656 seq.) A common example of such an account 
 is that between the banker and the customer. 
 
 In that case the capitalization of the interest generally takes 
 place at the end of the year, and interest is due upon every sum 
 advanced from its date, and so, likewise, upon every sum received 
 
DAMAGES FOR BREACH OF A PECUNIARY OBLIGATION. 249 
 
 to credit. But current accounts are also kept between traders, 
 and it has been held in Egypt that according to the usage of 
 commerce the capitalization was at the end of every three months. 
 (C. A. Alex. 14 mars 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 147. See Comptes 
 Gourants in Table Decennale, 1898 — 1908.} 
 
 English law as to interest on money-debts. 
 
 The old rule of the law was that interest cannot be claimed 
 unless there is evidence of an agreement to pay interest. But 
 there are important statutory exceptions. A jury may allow 
 interest by way of damages when the debt was a fixed sum pay- 
 able by virtue of a written instrument, or if not so payable, when 
 payment had been demanded in writing with notice that interest 
 would be claimed from the date of the demand. And interest 
 may be claimed in an action on a dishonoured bill of exchange. 
 (3 & 4 Will. IV. c. 42, ss. 28, 29; Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 
 s. 57; Anson on Contracts, 14th ed. p. 366. In the English 
 law the compounding of interest is not prohibited, but the Money- 
 lenders Acts, 1900 and 1911, enable the court to grant relief 
 against harsh and unconscionable contracts of loan. (See Anson, 
 Contracts, 14th ed. p. 220.) 
 
 4/ *V*1 Ur kk* /Wr ' ^ 
 
250 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XIV. 
 
 DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT 
 NOT BEING A CONTRACT TO PAY A SUM OF MONEY 
 
 This subject is dealt with in the Egyptian Code in articles which 
 axe substantially identical with the articles in the French Code. 
 (C. C. E. 121—123/179—181; C. C. F. 1149—1153.) 
 
 After stating that damages are not due unless the non-per- 
 formance or delay is due to the fault of the debtor, and that they 
 are not recoverable so long as .the debtor is not in default, the 
 code proceeds to lay down the rules as to the measure of damages. 
 It is customary to divide damages into two kinds: (1) compen- 
 satory, and (2) moratory. By compensatory damages is meant 
 the value in money of the interest that the creditor had in the 
 execution of the obligation. It is this sum which he is to receive 
 now that the obligation cannot be performed. He gets the money 
 value of the performance instead of the performance itself. By 
 moratory damages is meant the damages which the creditor suffers 
 by delay in the (execution. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 470: 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 157, note 19; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1147, n. 1.) 
 
 The main importance of this distinction is that when the object 
 of an obligation is the payment of a sum of money the only 
 damages are moratory damages. There is no question of ascer- 
 taining the value of the execution itself for it is always the pay- 
 ment of the sum of money stipulated. And, in consequence of 
 the difficulty of estimating in each particular case the loss caused 
 to the creditor by delay, the law fixes, as we have just explained, a! 
 universal rule for these damages, viz., the legal rate of interest 
 during the delay, and no other damages can be awarded. It is, 
 accordingly, convenient to deal separately as we have done with 
 the case where damages are sought for the breach of an obligation 
 to pay a sum of money. When the obligation is not one of this 
 kind the code says that, apart from the case of agreement to the 
 
DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT. 251 
 
 contrary, the damages consist in the amount of the loss sus- 
 tained by the creditor and of the profit which la- has failed I" 
 make, provided that the prejudice suffered is the direct and 
 
 immediate consequence of the non-performance. 
 
 Nevertheless, in the absence of fraud cm the part of I he debtor } 
 the damages recoverable "re only for that which could reasonably 
 have been foreseen at the time m the contract was mud'. 
 (C. C. E. 121, 122 179, 180. From these articles we see that 
 the general rule is that the creditor can claim damages under two 
 heads: (1) loss suffered — damnum emergens ; and (2) loss of profit 
 — lucrum, cessans. • 
 
 The French term dommages-interets is often said to allude to 
 these two elements. This is, perhaps, not historically correct, but 
 at any rate the term serves to remind us of the two elements. 
 (Laurent, 16, n. 283; Planiol, 2, n. 247.) But the rule that 
 the creditor can claim for the actual loss and the loss of profit is 
 subject to three clarifications: — 
 
 (1) Unless there was fraud on the part of the debtor, the 
 creditor can recover only the damages which could reasonably 
 have been foreseen at the date of the contract. (2) In any case, 
 even when there was fraud, the damages comprise only those which 
 are the direct and immediate consequence of the non-perform- 
 ance; and (3) if the parties have fixed beforehand by a penal 
 clause in the contract what the amount of the damages shall be 
 taken to be, this agreement is final. It is for the creditor who 
 claims damages under both these heads to prove his actual lo.-s 
 and also the failure of expected profit. But as the second element 
 is more or less problematical, the court has to estimate it from the 
 evidence before it. If a, public singer breaks his contract with an 
 impresario, the impresario can claim for expenses of the hall hired 
 for the performance, the advertising, and so forth, that is for money 
 actually out of pocket, and also for the loss of the profits which 
 he would have derived from the concert. What these profits would 
 have been it is impossible to determine with mathematical pre- 
 cision, but that is no reason why the court should not do its best 
 to. fix such a sum as will make good the loss. In a commercial 
 sale, at any rate for articles for which there is a regular market, 
 the seller who breaks his contract must make good to the purchaser 
 not only the value of the goods but the profit which he might have 
 made by -a resale. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 475; Pand. Franc, vo. 
 Oblig. n. 2092.) 
 
 If the vendor fails to deliver and the purchaser has to buy the 
 
 . 
 

 252 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 goods elsewhere at a higher price, the vendor is liable to pay the 
 difference. (Req. 27 fevr. 1894, D. 94. 1. 216.) It may be 
 that the price has gone down instead of up, in which case the 
 purchaser who can buy the goods for less than he promised will 
 have suffered no damages. (See C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1901, 
 B. L. J. XIII, 134; C. A. Alex. 8 avril 1908, B. L. J. XX, 
 165; C. A. Alex. 2 fevr. 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 135.) 
 
 The appreciation of the actual loss suffered or the loss of profit 
 and the amount of damages to be awarded must be left to the 
 discretion of the court. (Req. 28 oct. 1903, D. 1904. 1. 14.) 
 
 If the loss sustained is a moral loss only can the creditor 
 claim damages? 
 
 This is a very controversial question. Where damages are 
 claimed for delict or quasi-delict they are constantly given in cases 
 where only moral prejudice has been sustained. (C. A. Alex. 28 
 nov. 1917, B. L. J. XXX, 66.) For instance, the person who has 
 suffered from a libel can claim damages without proof of pecuniary 
 loss. C. A. Alex. 12 juin 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 351.) 
 
 The father of a child killed by the fault of another person may 
 not have sustained any pecuniary loss by the death of his child, 
 but he can claim for the moral j)rejudice. (C. A. Alex. 17 mai 
 1905, B L. J. XVII, 280; C. A. Alex. 12 juin 1918, B. L. J. 
 XXX, 469; C. A. 47 mars 1910, O. B. XI, n. Ill, p. 80. Cf. 
 Alger, 22 juin 1900, S. 1902. 2. 128. Does a different rule apply 
 in contracts? The French doctrine is divided. Some writers 
 deny that moral damages can be awarded in any case whether of 
 delict or of contract. (Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 1, 
 n. 480; 4, n, 2871.) 
 
 The principal arguments urged by the writers who support this 
 view are that the code contemplates only the reparation of material 
 loss which can be estimated in money. The use of the words 
 pertes el gains — " loss and -profit " — shows that it was the loss 
 of money only which the legislator had in mind. (C. C. F. 1149; 
 »'. C. E. 12L179.) 
 
 To make a defendant pay for a loss which w r as not pecuniary, 
 would be in effect to inflict a penalty upon him, and this Cannot 
 be done without an express text. These writers maintain that 
 the French jurisprudence is in this sense. The question seldom 
 presents itself squarely for decision, because in. most cases in which 
 
 i 
 
DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT. 253 
 
 moral prejudice has been caused by breach of contract there is 
 pecuniary loss also. For example, if a banker wrongfully refuses 
 to honour a cheque of a customer who has funds at his credit, the 
 loss of reputation caused by the dishonouring' of the cheque nm\ 
 affect the business of the drawer as well as cause him humiliation. 
 (Rouen, 27 mai 1844, D. Rep. Oblig. n. 777.) 
 
 And, in many cases, as we have seen, the courts compensate th 
 plaintiff for moral prejudice in an indirect manner by imposing 
 an astreinte upon the defendant. 
 
 But there are, undoubtedly, cases in which the French courte 
 have held that moral prejudice alone is not a ground for damages 
 in cases of breach of contract. 
 
 In one case where it was the duty of the defendant to deliver 
 to the plaintiff certain family portraits of no intrinsic value, and 
 there was a breach of this obligation, the court refused to award! 
 damages, giving as a reason, that the defendant's breach of contract 
 had not caused to the plaintiff any damage which was appreciable 
 in money. (Paris, 27 mars 1873, sous Req. 17 fevr. 1874, S. 
 74. 1. 477, D. 74. 1. 360, Journal du Palais, 74, p. 1218.) 
 
 And the opinion which prevails in the French doctrine is to 
 distinguish between breach of contract and delict or quasi-delict. 
 In the case of delict or quasi-delict, damages may be recovered 
 for moral prejudice, but in the case of breach of contract, the 
 only damages recoverable are for pecuniary loss. (Laurent, 16, 
 n. 281; Hue, 7, n. 147; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 170, note 
 39, ter; D. N. C. C. art. 1149, n. 29.) 
 
 But, although the French jurisprudence is conflicting, the 
 tendency is not to make the distinction for which these writers 
 contend. The most common case in France, in which damages 
 for moral prejudice are awarded, is that of the unjustifiable breach 
 of a promise of marriage. But, seeing that the promise to marry 
 is not enforceable, the French law considers the ground of action 
 here as delictual and not contractual. (Sourclat, Responsabilite, 
 1, n. 446, bis ; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 7, p. 41, note 26; Mantelet, 
 A., La Reparation du Prejudice Moral, These, Paris, p. 165; 
 Cass. 12 nov. 1901, S. 1902. 1. 237; Grenoble, 24 mars 1908, 
 D. 1910. 2. 134, and the note. Cf. the English Law, infra, 
 p. 255.) But there are not a few cases in which damages have 
 been awarded for moral prejudice caused by breach of contract 
 which cannot be explained by saying that the fault is delictual. 
 Thus, in the famous case against the painter Whistler for refus- 
 ing to deliver a portrait which he had contracted to paint, the 
 

 254 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 defendant, although he was not compelled to deliver the picture, 
 was ordered to return the price paid and to pay in addition a 
 thousand francs by way of damages. (Paris, 2 dec. 1897, D. 
 1898. 2. 465. Cf. Paris, 4 juillet 1865, D. 65. 2. 201, S. 65., 
 2. -233: Journal du Palais, 65, p. 937.) 
 
 And in cases of wrongous dismissal of an employee, it is 
 quite common to award damages for the moral prejudice as well 
 ls for the pecuniary loss caused by the dismissal. (Req. 22 mars 
 1904, D. 1904. 1. 449, and note by M. Planiol.) So, likewise, 
 it has been held that if a theatre-manager entrusts a role to an 
 actor, this implies a promise not to withdraw it if the actor plays 
 The part well. Where a. manager withdrew a part capriciously 
 be was held liable in damages for the moral prejudice. (Paris, 
 1 10 janv. 1863, Pand. Franc, vo. Acteurs, nos. 387, 388.) 
 
 The sound view appears to be that both in cases of breach 
 of contract and in cases of delict, moral prejudice is an element 
 which the court is entitled to take into account in estimating the 
 damages. It is perfectly settled that in cases of delict or quasi- 
 delict damages may be recovered for moral prejudice, and there 
 is no logical reason for refusing to apply the same rule in cases of 
 breach of contract. The language of the code does not render 
 such an interpretation impossible. There is no difference of nature 
 between that kind of fault which is a breach of contract and the 
 kind of fault which consists in the breach of a legal duty. As 
 M. Planiol says: La nature de V obligation violee reste sans 
 influence sur la laute. (2, n. 877. Cf. Saleilles, Theorie 
 -Generale de V Obligation, 3rd ed. n. 308; C. A. Alex 13 dec 
 1916, B. L. J. XXIX, 107.) 
 
 The objection often made, that if this theory is adopted the 
 court will have no sure basis for an estimation of the damages, is 
 by no means conclusive. It applies just as much in cases of delict 
 as in cases of contract, and in the former class of cases the courts 
 have not hesitated to appreciate moral damage. Why may they not 
 do the same in cases of breach of contract? Such an estimate may 
 be rough, but it must be left to the good sense of the courts. In 
 such a case as the one referred to above, where the duty was to 
 restore a family portrait, it is inadmissible to hold that if the 
 obligation arises from a contract, the debtor is entitled to say, 
 " I will throw the picture into the fire and pay you 25 piastres, 
 which is the market value of the picture." If the defendant had 
 destroyed the picture wrongfully, in a case where he was uncon- 
 nected by contract with the other party, he would have had to 
 
 
 
 
DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT. 255 
 
 pay for the moral prejudice, and there is no valid reason for not 
 coming to the same conclusion when the liability is contractual. 
 (In this sense, Chausse, M., De Vlnteret d" Affection, Rev. Crit. 
 1890, 430; Planiol, 2, n. 252; Mantelet, A., La Reparation du 
 Prejudice Moral, These, Paris, 1907, p. 103.) 
 
 English law. 
 
 Damages for breach of contract cannot by English law include 
 any compensation for loss which is not pecuniary. {Addis v. 
 Gramophone Co., 1909, A. C. 488, 78 L. J. K. B. 1122. But 
 actions for breach of promise form an exception to this rule. 
 Such an action, it has been said, is one which is based on the 
 hypothesis of a broken contract, yet it is attended with some of 
 the special consequences of a personal wrong, and in which damages 
 may be given of a vindictive and uncertain kind, not merely to 
 repay the plaintiff for temporal loss, but to punish the defendant 
 in an exemplary manner. (Pollock, Torts, 10th ed. p. 583. See 
 Finlay v. Chirney, 1888, 20 Q. B. D. 494, 57 L. J. Q. B. 247.) 
 
 Direct and immediate consequence. 
 
 In no case are the damages to exceed compensation for such 
 prejudice as is the direct and immediate consequence of the non- 
 performance. (C. C. E. 121/179; C. C. F. 1151.) The article 
 of the French Code upon which this rule is based is undoubtedly 
 founded upon a passage in Pothier, and all the French authorities 
 accept Pothier's discussion of the subject of damages as the best 
 commentary on the French Code. 
 
 Pothier explains that the line has to be drawn somewhere, and 
 that the debtor cannot be made to pay damages for losses not 
 necessarily connected with his act and which may have other 
 causes. And he gives as an illustration, the sale of a cow infected 
 with a contagious disease and known to be so by the seller. If 
 the purchaser puts the cow with his other cattle and they contract 
 the disease and die, this is a direct consequence of the fraudulent 
 concealment by the seller. But if the purchaser, having no stock 
 left on his farm, neglects to cultivate his land and becomes unable 
 to pay his debts, and his property is seized and sold at a low price 
 by his creditors, and in consequence of his misfortunes he commits 
 suicide, all these things are not the direct and immediate conse- 
 quences. (Oblig. n. 167. Cf . B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 488; Colmet 
 de Santerre, 5, n. 67 bis.) If a lessor fails to fulfil the pro- 
 
256 THK LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 visions of the lease and the lessee has to remove, the cost of removal 
 is a direct consequence. But if the lessee removes to a house in 
 which there has been smallpox and his child dies of it, this is not 
 a direct consequence of the lessor's fault. 
 
 If a reaping-machine is damaged in course of carriage, the 
 farmer who had bought it can claim damages from the carrier for 
 being deprived of its use during the time taken in repairing it or 
 in getting another, provided he uses due diligence. But he cannot 
 claim in addition damages for the loss of revenue which he might 
 have derived from the hire of his machine to neighbouring farmers, 
 for this loss is too indirect and problematical. (Cass. 3 mars 
 1897, D. 98. 1. 118.' If a part of a machine is sent to be 
 repaired and is lost in carriage, its owner cannot wait for months 
 and then claim for the loss he has suffered in having been deprived 
 of the machine during the whole season. He ought to have got 
 a new piece of the machine when he found the one sent to be 
 mended had been lost. (Thwuvilk v. Canadian Express Co., 
 1908, R. J.Q.33S.C.403.) 
 
 It is by no means easy in all cases to distinguish between those 
 consequences which are direct and those which are indirect, but 
 it is a matter for the appreciation of the court in the particular 
 case. • 
 
 One or two illustrations of what the courts regard as damages 
 which could have been foreseen will be given later. A recent 
 writer criticises the law, and maintains that the courts find it 
 impossible to fix a satisfactory criterion for distinguishing between 
 direct and indirect damages. (Pierre Marteau, La Notion de 
 la Causalite, These, Aix, 1914.) 
 
 Distinction based on absence of fraud. 
 
 In the absence of fraud the debtor does not necessarily have to 
 pay even for all the loss which is the direct consequence of his act. 
 He needs to pay only for that which could reasonably have been 
 foreseen at the time the contract was made. By " fraud " in this 
 connection the code does not mean the practising of any artifices 
 such as those which vitiate consent; it means merely bad faith. 
 
 The debtor who wilfully breaks his contract is guilty of fraud 
 in this sense, for he dishonestly cheats the expectation of the 
 creditor. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, m 483.) Where the debtor 
 has behaved in this way there is no reason why he should not be 
 made to pay for all the loss directly caused by his voluntary act. 
 
 
 wXju^* 
 
DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT. 257 
 
 Damages for that which could have been foreseen. 
 
 But when the debtor has behaved honestly his liability is 
 more limited; he must pay damages only for that "which 
 could reasonably have been foreseen." (C. C. E. 122/180.) 
 The Egyptian Code is upon this point clearer than the French. 
 It adds the word "reasonably." And it does not say that the 
 damages must have been capable of being foreseen. The French 
 Code says the debtor is liable only for the damages which were 
 foreseen or which might have been foreseen at the time of 
 the contract. (C. C. F. 1150.) There is a controversy as to 
 the exact meaning of these words. If the damages are due to 
 a cause which might have been foreseen, but they are greater 
 than was to have been expected, then according to one view in, 
 France, the debtor would be liable only for such damages as* 
 might have been expected to result from that cause. Damages 
 of a kind not to be expected though they arise from this cause* 
 are not covered. To hold otherwise, as the editors of the work 
 of MM. Aubry et Rau say, would be to amend the Frendh 
 article and to read it as if it ran: Le debiteitr nest teniu que 
 des dommages-interets dont la cause a ete prevue ou qui a pu 
 Vetre. The other view is that if the cause of the damage was 
 foreseen, or might have been foreseen, loss produced by that 
 cause must be paid for, although this loss could not have been 
 anticipated. For example, if in consequence of the lessor's breach 
 of his contract, the lessee has to remove and to take another house, 
 the lessor would have to pay for the cost of removal, for this is a 
 loss which might have been anticipated. But, if during the 
 occupation of the lessee, there has been an unexpected rise of rents 
 in the locality so that the lessee cannot get a similar house except 
 at a much higher rent, the lessor, according to the first view, would 
 not have to pay for this damage which could not have been anti- 
 cipated. (C. C. F. 1150; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 171. 
 note 41 . Contra, B.-L . et Bairde, Oblig. 1, n. 486 . Cf . C . C . F. 
 1633; C. C. E. 307/381. See Pau, 11 aout 1903, D. .1904. 
 2. 302.) But under the Egyptian Code there will be no difficulty; 
 in making the lessor liable because the damages are to be for 
 that which could reasonably have been foreseen. (C. C. E. 
 122/180.) And the cause of the damage, namely, the necessity 
 of taking another house, was clearly something which might have 
 been anticipated. 
 
 Where there has been no fraud, in the sense explained above. 
 
 17 
 
 W. — VOL. II. 
 
 
258 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 on the part of the debtor, the question whether damages could or 1 
 could not have been reasonably foreseen is of course one of fact. 
 But the law desires to excuse a debtor from, having- to pay 
 damages which he could not have contemplated when he made the 
 contract. He is, it is true, in fault or he would not have to pay 
 damages at all. But he has not intended to cause injury to the 
 creditor, and, therefore, the law treats him with a certain indul- 
 gence. He is more favourably regarded than the man who has 
 caused damage by an unlawful act, who has committed a delict 
 or a quasi-delict, as distinguished from a breach of contract. The 
 author of an unlawful act is liable to pay all the damages directly 
 caused by his act whether he could have foreseen these damages or 
 not. He must repair the damage. (C. C. E. 151/212.) This 
 distinction between the measure of damages for breach of contract 
 without "fraud" as opposed to that for wrongful acts is not, 
 perhaps, very logical. It is commonly defended by saying that 
 in the case of a contract each of the parties is presumed to con- 
 template the possible breach of the contract. He has the power 
 to insist on stipulations framed with a view to prevent or diminish 
 the loss which he may suffer by the breach of contract. If he 
 insists on no special stipulation he may be presumed to have 
 trusted to the good faith of the other party. Each of the parties 
 in making his calculations takes into account the possibility of his 
 own breach of the contract, and estimates the amount of damages 
 which he may have to pay for this breach. On the other hand, 
 in the case of wrongs the injured party has not entered into any- 
 voluntary relation with the other, and there is no reason why he 
 should not recover all the damages he has suffered, whether they 
 could reasonably have been anticipated or not. (See Sourdat, 
 Responsabilite, 1, n. 691.) 
 
 Illustrations of the rule as to damages which might have 
 
 been foreseen. 
 
 A, who is bound subject to a penalty to deliver certain goods 
 to B, orders the goodis from C, without informing him of the terms 
 of his contract with B. C breaks his contract. A cannot recover 
 from him the penalty which he has to pay to B. (See Req. 27 
 fevr. 1894, D. 94. 1. 395.) 
 
 In consequence of delay on the part of a railway-company, the 
 sender of goods given to them for carriage is unable to fulfil his 
 contract with the consignee, and the contract is resiliated. In 
 
DAMAGES RECOVERABLE FOR BREACH OF A CONTRACT. 259 
 
 default of proof that the railway-company could have foreseen 
 this result of their delay they are not liable for the loss caused to 
 the sender by the resiliation of the contract. T'ass. 21 now 1910, 
 D. 1911. 1. 208.) 
 
 A passenger who is intending to ride a horse in a race arrives 
 at his destination too late to do so. He cannot recover from the 
 railway-company the damages which he has suffered by not taking 
 part in the race, at least unless the railway-company knew the 
 object of his journey, and foresaw or might have foreseen the 
 special risk which they were incurring. (Cass. 29 janv. 1908, 
 D. 1910, 1. 280. Cf. Cas. 22 nov. 19U4, L>. 1907. 1. 415; 
 Cons. d'Etat, 20 avril, 1877, D. 77. 3. 73.) A railway-company 
 can foresee that passengers will carry with them in their luggage 
 articles of more or less considerable value. But they are not 
 expected to foresee that a passenger will carry in this way things 
 of quite exceptional value, having regard to the position of the 
 passenger, the object of the voyage and the price of the ticket. 
 They cannot expect that a trunk registered as passenger's luggage 
 contains merchandise worth 16,000 francs. (Cass. 20 dec. 1913, 
 D. 1916. 1. 117.) 
 
 We may compare a leading English case. Owing to delay in 
 the delivery of a piece of machinery which was in course of transit 
 a mill was kept idle. It was held the carrier was not liable for 
 the damages so caused,. (Hadley v. Baxendale, 1854, 9 Ex. 341, 
 96 E. B. 742. Cf. Bostock & Co., Ltd. v. Nicholson & Sons, 
 Ltd., 1904, 1 K. B. '725, 73 L. J. K. B. 523; Hammond v. 
 Bussey, 1887, 20 Q. B. D. 79, 57 L. J. Q. B. 58; Anson, 
 Contracts, 14th ed. p. 367; Mayne on Damages, 8th ed. p. 12.) 
 
 Distinction in other laws. 
 
 The German Code altogether rejects this distinction and makes 
 the person who is found liable in damages, whether it be for breach 
 of contract or for a wrong, bound to make good the whole loss. 
 He must " restore things to the position in which they would have 
 been if the event which made him liable had not happened*'' 
 (art. 249. See Hindenburg, Eevue Critique, 1901, XXX*, p. 26; 
 Cosack, Lehrbuch des Deutsdhem hiirgerlichen Rechts, 6th ed. 
 1, p. 373.) 
 
 And in the English law ,the damages for breach of contract 
 are limited to compensation for such loss as a reasonable man 
 
 17 (2) 
 
260 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 might have expected to result from the breach. (Hadley v. Baxen- 
 dale, ut supra.) But in the English law the liability of a defen- 
 dant, even in the case of tort, is similarly restricted. He is not 
 responsible for all the damage which he has caused, but only for 
 (1) damage which he intended, or (2) damage which is the natural 
 or probable consequence of the wrongful act. All other damage 
 is too remote. (See Salmond, Torts, 4th ed. p. 126; Pollock, 
 Torts, 10th ed. p. 30; Halsbury, Laics of England, vo. Damages, 
 p. 313; Mayne on Damages, 8th ed. pp. 54 seq.) 
 
 This rule of the English law as to the measure of damages for 
 torts is practically identical with the French rule under discussion, 
 for if a loss is the "natural and probable result" it is a loss. 
 "which could reasonably have been foreseen." 
 
 Clause of penalty. 
 
 The rules when the amount of the damage is determined by 
 the contract will be explained under Obligations with a Penal 
 Clause. 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 261 
 
 CHAPTER XV. 
 
 STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 
 
 A contract may contain a clause that, iiiJjia_eveni_i}fJ.ts-jaot- 
 being duly performed by the debtor, he shall not be liable in 
 damages, and that, even though tin- breach of contract shall bo 
 caused by his fault, or by the fault of persons for whom he is 
 normally responsible. Stipulations of this kind arc commonly 
 spoken of in the French law as clauses $ exoneration or clauses 
 de non-responsabilite. To what extent are such stipulations valid 
 if they are clearly expressed? Few questions in the French law 
 have given rise to more dispute, and even now the law can hardly 
 be regarded as settled. (See Boutaud, E., Des Clauses de Non- 
 responsabilite ; Sourdat, Responsabilite, 5th ed. 1, nos. 662, 
 septies; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 12; Becque, E., in Rev. Trim. 
 1914, p. 311; Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 176; Thaller, Traite Elemen- 
 tairc de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. p. 604; Josserand, Les 
 Transports, nos. 622 seq. ; Cass. 31 dec. 1900, S. 1901. 1. 401, 
 and note by M. E. Perreau; Req. 9 dec. 1902, D. 1903. 1. Ill; 
 Dissertation by M. Sarrut in note to Cass. 9 mars 1886, D. 90. 
 1.209.) 
 
 Restrictive interpretation. 
 
 Upon general principles of interpretation such clauses must be 
 interpreted restrictively. (Cass. 19 fevr. 1900, D. 1900. 1. 433.) 
 
 Debtor cannot stipulate against his own dol or faute lourde. 
 
 It is contrary to elementary notions of good faith to allow a 
 man who binds himself by a contract to stipulate at the same time 
 that if he breaks the contract intentionally he shall not be liable 
 in damages. As the Roman law said: Si convener it, ne dolus 
 prcestatur : hoc enim bonce fidei judicio conlrarium est. (Dig. 
 50. 17. 23.) And there is a degree of negligence so gross that 
 the law assimilates it to a wilful intention to break the contract. 
 
262 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 If the debtor in the contract shows such negligence as to indicate- 
 complete indifference to the interests of the other party, it would 
 be against public policy to let him escape his liability by pleading 
 that he had stipulated for immunity. Culpa lata dolo equiperatur. 
 (See Dig. 16. 3. 32; Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 654.) These 
 rules taken from the Roman law have always formed a part of 
 the French law. (Sourdat, RespotisabiUte. I.e.; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 1, n. 360, and 4, n. 2869; Cass. 15 mars 1876, S. 76. 1. 
 337, Journal du Palais, 76, p. 833, and note by Labbe; .Req. 
 27 nov. 1911, D. 1913. 1. Ill: Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 176; Planiol, 
 2, n. 882.) 
 
 The Egyptian jurisprudence is in the same sense. (C. A. 
 Alex. 21 dec. 1894, B. L. J. VII, 11; C. A. Alex. 16 nov. 1898, 
 B. L. J. XI, 14; Trib. Mixte, Caire, 11 mai 1907, B. L. J. 
 XX, 131; Trib. Mixte, Alex. 15 juin 1912, Gaz. Trib. 4, n. 273.) 
 Even the donor or the lender in the contract of loan for use is., 
 always liable for his dol or faute lourde, although his obligation 
 is gratuitous. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 360.) 
 The Cow de Cassation stated the rule in these terms: Aitendu 
 qu.il n'est pas permis, au moyen d'un contrat d'assurance ou de 
 tout autre pacte, de stipuler d'avance Vimmunite de ses fautes 
 lourde s : que Vordre public s' oppose a la validite d'un tel pacte. 
 (Cass. 15 mars 1876, S. 76. 1. 337, D. 76. 1. 449.) 
 
 Indeed, there would be little virtue in contracts if the parties 
 were allowed to stipulate that they might play fast and loose 
 with them. 
 
 The reason for the prohibition in this case is in fact the same 
 which underlies the provision of C. C. F. 1174: Toute obligation 
 est nulle lorsqu'elle a etc oontraetee sous une condition potestative, 
 de la part de celui qui s' oblige. (Boutaud, Clauses de non- 
 responsabilite, p. 224.) 
 
 There are a few French writers who reject the assimilation 
 between dol and faute lourde, and maintain that a stipulation of 
 exoneration for faute lourde is valid, though one of immunity from 
 dol is void. (Boutaud, Des Clauses de non-responsabilitL p. 225; - 
 Sainctelette, Responsabilite et Garcmtie, 17. See Josserarid, Les 
 Transports, n. 624, p. 516.) But this opinion is contrary to the- 
 traditional view, and to the weight of modern French authority. 
 
 f,UJL hah* ft, >Wl WA <v<\*>wH 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 263 
 
 Stipulations of exoneration for fault of prepose. 
 
 Does the same principle apply when the stipulation is that the 
 debtor shall not be responsible for the fault of his prepose ? The 
 view which prevails in France is in favour of the affirmative. 
 (Sourdat, Responsabilite, 2, n. 796; note by M. Sarrut to Cass. 
 18 juill. 1900, D. 1903. 1. 17.) If it is against public policy to 
 refuse to allow a man to stipulate that he may break his contract 
 at will or that he may show a negligence so gross as to be equiva- 
 lent to the intention to break the contract, why should he be 
 allowed to do these things by the instrumentality of others? The 
 French jurisprudence is in this sense. 
 
 In a' recent case the Chambre des Requetes stated the rule thus: 
 Attendu qu'il n'sst pas plus permis de s'exonerer par avanoe par 
 convention des fautes de ses preposes que de ses propres fautes ; 
 que, s'il pent en etre autrement, cest seulement lorsque le prepose 
 echappe en fait, dans Vexeroice de ses fonctions, a Vautorite du 
 preposant et de sa direction. (Req. 27 nov. 1911, D. 1913. 1. 
 111. Cf. Cass. 31 dec. 1900, S. 1901. 1. 404, D. 1903. 1. 17: 
 Rev. Trim. 1914, p. 315; Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 176.) 
 
 The principle has been followed in Egyptian jurisprudence. 
 (C. A. Alex. 16 nov. 1898, B. L. J. XI, 14.) 
 
 The reservation made by the Chambre des Requetes of cases 
 in which the prepose is not in fact subject to the control of 
 the preposant is illustrated by two well recognised exceptions to 
 the rule: — 
 
 (1 ) It is admitted that a commissionnaire de transport, or " for- 
 warding agent " as he is called in the Egyptian Commercial Code, 
 may, by a clause in the way-bill, exonerate himself for liability 
 for loss caused by the acts of the carrier or intermediate agent to 
 whom he consigns the goods. (C. Comm. F. 98; C. Comm. E. 
 92/97; Paris, 19 mars 1907, D. 1909. 2. 350; Lyon-Caen et 
 Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 624; Jos- 
 serand, Les Transports, n. 736.) 
 
 (2) In the law of carriage of goods by sea the French juris- 
 prudence appears to be settled that the ship-owner may, by a 
 clause in the bill of lading, exonerate himself from his liability to 
 the shippers of goods for loss caused by. the captain and crew 
 of the ship. (O. Com. F. 216; Cass. 25 oct. 1899, S. 99. 1. 
 496; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Manuel de Droit Commercial 11th 
 ed. n. 881, Traite de Droit Comm., 4th ed. 5, n. 744; Boutaud, 
 
264 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Des Clauses de mm-responsabilite, pp. 267,429; Rev. Trim. 1914, 
 p. 314. 
 
 But in spite of the reasons above given against allowing a com- 
 mettant to stipulate immunity for the faute lourde of his prepose, 
 supported as they arc by the French jurisprudence, it must be 
 admitted that a clause of non-liability for the fault of one's agents 
 stands in a different position from aclause of non-liability for one's 
 own fault. It is contended by some French writers that there is 
 no public policy against a man stipulating that he will not be 
 responsible even for the faute lourde of his prepose. (Boutaud, 
 op. elt. p. 220: Sarrut, in note to Cass. 9 mars 1886, D. 90. 1. 
 212; Becque, Rev. Trim. 1914, p. 318. See Josserand, Les 
 Transports, n. 624, p. 516.) It will be mentioned presently that 
 this is the tendency in legislation. 
 
 In assimilating as it does the faute lourde of the prepose with 
 the faute lourde of the preposant himself, the French law goes 
 further than is reasonable. There are cases no doubt in which 
 the faute lourde of the servant or agent involves at the same time 
 the faute lourde of the master or principal. There may have 
 been gross negligence in the choice of a subordinate, or an entire 
 absence of reasonable supervision. But there are other cases in 
 which the faute lourde on the part of the subordinate is consistent. 
 with merely slight fault or no fault at all on the part of the 
 
 aster or principal. He may have taken every reasonable care 
 in the choice of his subordinate, and he may have exercised every 
 reasonable supervision over his conduct. In cases of this kind, 
 if the other party has been willing to contract that the preposant 
 shall not be liable, upon what reason of public policy must such a 
 stipulation be invalid, at any rate unless the contract is one which 
 involves the public health or safety? It may be reasonable to 
 say that the preposant shall be necessarily liable for the dol of his 
 prepose in order to prevent the possibility of connivance between 
 the'two. But the reasons for extending the same principle to the 
 faute lourde of the prepose are far from conclusive. (See Sarrut, 
 in note to Cass. 9 mars 1886, D. 90. 1. 209; Boutaud, Des Clauses 
 de non-responsabiUte, pp. 226 seq. ; Becque, E., in Rev. Trim. 
 1914, pp. 316 seq.) 
 
 Stipulation of immunity for one's own ordinary negligence 
 or the ordinary negligence of one's prepose. 
 
 According to the prevailing view in the French doctrine and 
 jurisprudence, such stipulations are valid if the debtor's duty to 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 265 
 
 exercise care is derived solely from the' contract. The famous 
 distinction is made between faute contractuelh and jaute delic- 
 tuelle. The debtor may validly exonerate himself from his lia- 
 bility created by contract except as regards dol and faute lourde, 
 but he cannot exonerate himself beforehand for a delict or a quasi- 
 delict, for his responsibility in these cases is a matter of public 
 order. (Baudry-Laeant. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. '28(5!); Sourdat, 
 Responsabilite, 5th ed. 1, n. 662 septies. See Josserand, Les 
 Transports, n. 866; C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 1908, B.L.J. XXr, 93.) 
 
 Before deciding whether the clause is valid or invalid, we must 
 examine the contract to see if it is one which involves any ques- 
 tion of public order. In some contrasts it is completely indiffe- 
 rent to the state whether the contract is performed or not; the 
 matter is one which interests the parties only. They were free 
 to contract or not to contract as they chose, and they may annex 
 such conditions as they like to the contract which they make. 
 Thus, for example, if a workman undertakes to repair a fragile 
 vase he may make it a condition of the contract that if he breaks 
 it, even negligently, he is not to be responsible. Dig- 9. 2. 27. 
 29. Or a mandatary or depositary may stipulate that he will 
 not be responsible for any risks to the thing entrusted to him. 
 (Pothier, Mandat, n. 50; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit 
 Commercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 626 bis; Dall. Supp. vo. Responsa- 
 bilitc, n. 253.) In such cases there was no antecedent duty on the 
 part of the workman, the mandatary, or the depositary. If he 
 chose to undertake the duty he could impose any lawful conditions, 
 and if he fails to keep his contract his failure is a breach of 
 contract, and nothing more. 
 
 But there are other contracts which stand in a different posi- 
 tion, lor example, an owner of property owes a duty to the 
 public that it shall not be dangerous to them. And if the lessee of 
 the property suffers personal injuries resulting from the giving- 
 way of a portion of the structure leased, the fault of the owner, 
 according to the better opinion, is not contractual, but delictual. 
 (See Dall. Hep. vo. Louage, n. 191; 32 Rev. Prat. pp. 558 seq. ; 
 Laurent, 16, n. 230; Vineberg v. Foster, 1903, R. J. Q. 24 
 S. C. 258.) 
 
 An employer has a duty to take care of his workmen, and if 
 one of them is injured by the negligence of the master or of a 
 fellow-w T orkman, the fault of the master is a faute delictudle and 
 not. a, faute contractuelh '. This, at any rate, is the view of the 
 French jurisprudence and of the greater part of the doctrine, 
 though there are important dissentients. (Rcq. 15 juill. 1896, 
 
266 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 D. 98. 1. 141; D. N. C. C. IV, p. 9-34, n. 52. See Boutau,d,,. 
 Des Clauses de non-re$pomabiIiU\ p. 86; Sourdat, Responsabilite, 
 5th ed. 2, n. 913, quater, and n. 1487; C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 1908, 
 B.L.J. XXI, 93.) 
 
 A railway -company owes a duty to take care of persons who 
 are, with its permission, in its vehicles or upon its premises wdietlier 
 they have a contract with the' rail way -company or not. ('See 
 Josserand, Les Transports, n. 849. Cf. Toulouse, 4 mai 1900, 
 and Req. 18 mars 1912, S. 1913. 1. 430; Rev. Trim. 1914. 
 p. 500.) 
 
 These illustrations are sufficient to show that there are many 
 cases in which there is a duty owing to a person by law and at the 
 same time a duty owing to him under a contract. It does not, 
 however, follow that the person to whom the duty was owed may 
 not by his contract have released the other party from both duties 
 if it was competent for him to do so. 
 
 But, as already stated, the general view in France is that it is 
 not competent for him to release the other from the duty imposed 
 by law apart from any contract. 
 
 Concurrence of faute contractuelle and faute delictuelle in 
 other systems of law. 
 
 The principle that an act may be at the same time a breach of 
 contract and a wrong, so that a choice of remedies is presented to 
 the person injured, was admitted by the Roman law and is admitted 
 under the English law. The conditions of the two remedies may 
 be different as regards the period of prescription, the amount of 
 damages which can be recovered, the transmissibility of the right 
 of action to heirs and successors, and so forth, and it is, therefore, 
 an advantage for the victim that he has two strings to his bow. 
 The breach of the duty created by the contract and the breach of 
 the general duty which lies upon every one not to injure another 
 by his fault are clearly two different things . It is not correct to say 
 that when there is a contract between two persons one of them is 
 allowed to do to the other anything which is not forbidden by the 
 contract. In the Roman law there were various reasons which give 
 some importance to this doctrine, but these do not need to be 
 considered here. (See Dig. 44. 7. 34. 2; Dig. 9. 2. 27. 29; 
 Grueber, E., Roman Late of Damage to Property, pp. 24, 100, 
 210, 230; Vangerow, Pandelien, 7th ed. 3, s. 681, p. 590; Wind- 
 scheid, Pandekten, 8th ed. 2, s. 455, note 12.) 
 
 In the English law also it is a well-settled rule that the same 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 267 
 
 facts may give to A both a remedy in contract and a remedy in. 
 tort against B. 
 
 " If a common law duty results from the facts the party may be 
 sued in tort for any negligence or misfeasance in the execution of 
 the contract." (Chitty, Pleadings, I, 135; Pollock, Torts, 10th 
 ed. p. 560; Gooiey, Torts, 3rd ed. 1, p. 155.) If the injury would 
 have been a tort if there had been no contract, the contract does 
 not take away the right to sua in tort. The simplest case is that 
 in which a man has bound himself to perform some duty which 
 lies upon him antecedently apart from the contract. A doctor or 
 a dentist who by negligence injures a patient is in this position; 
 his negligence is both a breach of a contract and a tort. {Edwards 
 v. Mallcm, 1908, 1 K. B. 1002, 77 L. J. K. B. 608.) But 
 there are more difficult cases which do not need to be considered 
 here. (See Salmond, Torts, 4th ed. p. 3.) 
 
 Thus, in a railway case, a mother was travelling with a young 
 child just above the age at which children were entitled to travel 
 free. The mother took a ticket for herself *only . The child was 
 injured by the negligence of the company's servants, and an action 
 of damages was brought by the child. It was held that the com- 
 pany was liable either on an entire contract to carry the mother and 
 the child, or independently of contract, because the child was 
 accepted as a passenger, and this cast a duty on the company to 
 carry him safely. (Austin v. Great Western Railway Co., 1867, 
 L.R.2Q.B. 442, 36 L. J. Q. B. 201.) But, apart from certain 
 special cases which do not need to be mentioned here, the English 
 law sees no difficulty in a man renouncing beforehand by contract 
 his right to claim damages for a tort. (See infra, p. 282.) 
 
 Is it a universal rule of the French law that a man by contract 
 cannot relieve himself from liability for a quasi-delict? 
 
 Many writers say* broadly, that all clauses of exoneration from 
 liability for quasi-delicts are null as being against public policy. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 4, n. 2869; Sourdat, Responsa- 
 bilite, 1, n. 662, septies ; Dall. Supp. vo. Responsabilite,n. 253; 
 Rand. Frang. vo. Respanmbilite, nos. 2021 seq.) 
 
 The most recent jurisprudence of the Cour de Cassation appears 
 at first sight, at any rate, to be in this sense. (Cass. 31 dec. 1900, 
 D. 1903. 1. 17, S. 1901. 1. 401; Req. 27 nov. 1911, D. 1913. 
 1. 111.) But these cases must be taken with reference to their 
 particular facts and will be noticed later. 
 
 L\ ivf-AMM U fill „ t... 
 
268 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 It does not seem that any considerations of public policy render 
 necessary the acceptance of so broad a principle. On the con- 
 trary, the carrying on of affairs would be difficult if parties were 
 not allowed to relieve themselves from such liability. What 
 public policy is there to prevent a man undertaking to do certain 
 work on condition that he shall not be responsible for damage 
 caused by the negligence of his workmen? Apart from contract, 
 his liability for their negligence would be quasi-delictual, but 
 thai term does not involve any personal fault of his. It may be 
 that there was a want of care on his part, but this is not necessarily 
 the case. The question has been discussed in France mainly in 
 regard to contracts with common carriers by land. Under the 
 commercial codes the carrier is held to warranty against the loss 
 and damage of the goods carried, unless the loss or damage pro- 
 ceed front defects inherent in the thing, from vis major, or from the 
 fault or negligence of the consignor. (C. Comm. E. 97/102; 
 C. Comm. F. 103.) 
 
 But if the carrier stipulates that he will take the goods on 
 condition that he will not be responsible for loss, what is the effect 
 of such a stipulation? The French law on this subject lias gone 
 through three stages: — 
 
 1 From the passing of the codes down to 1874, the courts 
 held that the clause was altogether null. It was contrary to public 
 order because it encouraged negligence and placed the shipper 
 of the goods entirely at the mercy of the carrier. (Thaller, Traite 
 Elementmre de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. n. 1200; Lyon-Caen 
 et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 626; Lyon- 
 Caen et Renault, Manuel de Droit Commercial, 11th ed. n. o24.j 
 
 (2) After 1874 the courts came to take a different view of the 
 matter. They held that the clause of exoneration was not null 
 but it produced only a restricted effect, namely, that of altering 
 the onus of proof. Apart from stipulation, if the carrier could 
 not produce the goods safely at the end of the transit, it-was for 1 
 him to prove that they had been lost or damaged without his 
 fault. If, however, the carrier stipulated immunity from his 
 liability, the effect of this was that if he failed to deliver the 
 goods safely to the consignee no damages were due unless it was 
 proved that the loss or damage was caused by the fault of the 
 carrier or his servants. The jurisprudence became absolutely 
 settled in this sense by a long series of decisions. (Cass. 7 juin 
 1904, D. '06. 1. 17-3; Req. 9 nov. 1898, S. 99. 1. 398. See the 
 cases collected in Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 5, p. 624, note 10; 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 269 
 
 and Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, 
 n. 626.) This interpretation of the clause of exoneration was 
 vehemently criticised by the doctrine, and it was indeed entirely 
 arbitrary. It might be logical, though unreasonable, to say thai 
 such stipulations were null, but it was neither logical nor reason- 
 able to pronounce them valid up to a certain point but to give 
 them a meaning which the parties never contemplated. More- 
 over, no great protection was afforded to the public by such an 
 arbitrary method of interpretation. If the owner of the goods 
 lost or damaged has to prove any specific fault on the part of the 
 carrier or his servants, it is seldom that he will be able to do so. 
 As a rule all that he knows is that the goods do not arrive at 
 their destination or arrive in a damaged condition. 
 
 (3) The third phase of the law was brought about by the hi de 
 17 mars 1905, called the loi Rubier, which has added to C. Comm. 
 F. 103 an alinea in these terms: — 
 
 Toute clause contraire inseree dans toute lettre de voiture, tarif, 
 ou autre piece quelconque, est nulle. 
 
 This law applies to all carriers except carriers by sea, but it 
 does not extend to the carriage of persons, though her.' the reasons 
 of public policy apply a fortiori. (Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite 
 de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 715, and 5, n. 743; Caen, 
 7 juin 1907, Toulouse, 8 avril, 1908, S. 1908. 2. 125 and 144, 
 D. 1909. 2. 124. Cf . Besangon, 27 janv. 1911, D. 1913. 2. 114; 
 Req. 10 dec. 1907, D. 1913. 1. 45; infra, p. 272.) And the law 
 applies only to the loss of the goods or damage caused to them 
 and not to loss caused by delay in their delivery. (Lyon-Caen et 
 Renault, I.e.; Thaller, Traite Elementaire de Droit Commercial, 
 4th ed. n. 1203 . ) Moreover, the loi Eabier leaves the railway-com- 
 pany or other carrier free to make stipulations limiting the amount 
 of damages to be paid in the event of loss, though the courts might 
 annul such a clause if the damages were so small as to destroy the 
 responsibility of the carrier. (Lyon-Caen et Renault, I.e. The 
 soundness of this conclusion is doubted by M. Thaller, who con- 
 siders that on a correct interpretation of the law it annuls not only 
 clauses of non-responsibility but also clauses limiting the respon- 
 sibility tc a maximum sum (n. 1205). 
 
 Since the passing of the hi Babjer the railway-company in 
 France can escape its liability for loss of or damage to goods 
 carried, only by proving: 
 
 (1) That the loss was caused by a defect inherent in the thing, 
 vice propre; or 
 • 
 
270 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (2; bj force majeure; or 
 
 (3) by the fault of the consignor. (Thaller, I.e.; Josserand, 
 Les Transports, n. 609; and see the full note by M. Bourcart sous 
 Trib. de Paix de Saint- Vivien, 15 mai 1907, S. 1908. 2. 145.) 
 
 M;my French writers are of the opinion, in which I agree, that 
 the lm Habier is unreasonably strict and that it would be more 
 in the interest of public order to leave greater freedom to the- 
 parties. Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 
 4th ed. 3, n. 626 bis; Josserand, Les Transports, n. 636.) 
 
 Egyptian cases in contract of Carriage. 
 
 In Egypt the rules of the French jurispruderlce as to the effect 
 of clauses of exoneration have been closely followed. It is agreed 
 that such clause* cannot liberate the carrier from his liability 
 for dolor faute lourde. (C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1917, Gaz. Trib. 
 7. p. 73; Trib. Comm. Alex. 8 mai 1911, Gaz. Trib. 1, p. 133; 
 Trib. Somm. Alex. 4 janv. 1919, Gaz. Trib. 9, p. 48.) 
 
 But clauses exonerating the carrier from his liability for the 
 negligence of his employees, or limiting his liability to a fixed 
 amount in the event of loss, are not regarded as against public 
 policy. Following the French jurisprudence as it was before the 
 passing of the loi Rabier, .the Egyptian courts hold that such 1 
 clauses have the effect of inverting the onus of proof. In the 
 principal case the law was thus stated: Une pareille clause n'a 
 pas pour effet d'exonerer le voiturier des soins qxCil est term 
 d'apporter, suivant le droit commun, a la garde et a la conserva- 
 tion de la merchandise qui lui a ete confiee; elle tend uniquement 
 a limiter sa responsabilite a une ualeur qui a ete expressement 
 et tacitement fixee par les parties elles-memes, pour le cas ou 
 elles se tmuveraient dans Vimpossibilite de remplir les devoirs 
 d-e preuve qui lew incombent respectivement, en ce qui regarde 
 soit la faute de voiturier (dont it a necessairement a repondre, 
 nonobstant toute convention contraire, des quelle est etablie en 
 fait),smt la foroe majeure qui a pour effet de le decharger de 
 toute responsabilite. (C. A. Alex. 18 janv. 1900, B. L. J. 
 XII, 90. 
 
 In another case where goods of a very fragile nature Mere sent 
 by train and many of them were broken en route, it was proved 
 that they had been unloaded by mistake at the station of Cairo 
 and reloaded again to send to the station of Abul Ela to whicih 
 they were addressed. The bill of lading contained a clause of 
 non-warranty, and it was proved that the administration offered 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 271 
 
 the sender of the goods an option either to send them under this 
 bill of lading with the clcwae de uon-garantie, or to have them 
 sent with a man to look after them, or to insure them foil a small 
 premium. It was held that seeing- that this option was offered 
 to the consignor of the goods the clause of non-warranty could not 
 be considered as unlawful, but that the Railway Administration 
 was liable inasmuch as fault had been proved by the fact of their 
 having unloaded the goods at the wrong station. (C. A. Alex. 
 16 mai 1900, B. L. J. XII, 251.) 
 
 In another case part of the goods sent had disappeared en route. 
 There was no reasonable explanation of this except that the goods 
 had been stolen by the servants of the railway or owing to their 
 grave negligence. In these circumstances it was held that the 
 Railway Administration was liable for the full value of the goods 
 stolen and could not rely upon the clause restricting its liability 
 to a certain sum. (Trib. Somm. Alex. 4 janv. 1919, Gaz. Trib. 
 9, p. 48. Cf. C. A. Alex. 18 fevr. 1914, Gaz. Trib. 4, p 108, 
 n. 273.) 
 
 In the two cases last cited there was proof of faute lourde, 
 and it was therefore not necessary to decide whether a clause of 
 non-liability would be a complete defence if the fault alleged was 
 ordinary negligence. But in the two cases decided by the Mixed 
 Court of Appeal (B. L. J. XII, 90, and B. L. J. XII, 251) the 
 question was as to ordinary negligence, and the French juris- 
 prudence, according to which the onus of proof is shifted by the 
 clause of exoneration, was followed in these cases. (See article 
 by present writer in Gaz. Trib. 1919, 9, p. 139.) 
 
 Special reasons of public policy in regard to contracts of 
 
 carriage. 
 
 .There are reasons which do not apply to contracts in general 
 why contracts made with common carriers should be regarded 
 with jealousy. (1) Negligence in the carriage of persons is likely 
 to result in loss of life or personal injury, and under modern, 
 conditions of society one can hardly say that persons are free to 
 travel or not as they like. Frequently, also, the carrier to whom 
 they trust the safety of their lives and limbs enjoys a monopoly. 
 It is in the public interest that travelling should be as safe as 
 possible, and any stipulations which tend to relax the diligence 
 of railway companies and other carriers by land in the exercise 
 of their duty to take care of life and limb are against public order. 
 Since the lot Rabier in France it can hardly be doubted that this 
 
272 'i'HE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 is the French law, for, although that law doos not apply to the 
 carriage of persons, the reason of public policy which underlies 
 the law applies to that case a fgriiori. (2) If the carrier cannot 
 relievo himself from his fault in regard to the carriage of goods, 
 it would be strange indeed if he could do so in regard to the 
 carriage of persons. (3) It is contrary to public policy that one. 
 man should give to another the right to kill or injure him with 
 impunity even though it be without dot or faute lourde. Almost 
 all the French writers agree upon this point. (Sarrut, in note 
 to Cass. 21 nov. 1911, D. 1913. 1. 250; Labbe, in note to Cass. 
 ler juill. 1885, S. 1885. 1. 409; Josserand, L., Les Transports, 
 n. 915; Becque, E., in Rev. Trim. 1914, p. 319.) 
 
 According to the latest jurisprudence of the Cow d,e Cassation 
 the liability of the carrier of passengers is contractual and not 
 delictual, the contract being to carry the passenger safe and sound 
 to his destination. If the contract is not duly performed the 
 carrier is liable unless he prove that the accident was due to the 
 fault of the victim or to force majeure. (Cass. 21 nov. 1911, 
 S. 1912. 1. 73. Cf. Paris, 2 fevr. 1910, Pond. Frang. Periodi- 
 ques, 1910. 2. 223; Rev. Trim. 1913, p. 432; Rev. Trim. 1915, 
 p. 189.) 
 
 The Mixed Court of Appeal in one case appears to have 
 accepted this view. (C. A. Alex. 16 juin 1897, B. L. J. IX, 
 388.) 
 
 This question belongs to the law of responsibility, and cannot 
 be discussed here. 
 
 But it may be mentioned here that the history of article 1784 
 of the French Code, as well as the terms of that article itself, 
 make it very doubtful if the common carrier was intended to be 
 an insurer of passengers. (See Ripert, G., in Rev. Critique, 
 1913, p. 198; Josserand, Las Transports, n. 879.) * 
 
 And it is interesting to notice that in the English law the view 
 that he is such an insurer has been definitely rejected. (Gallin 
 v. L. & N. W. By., 1875, L. R. 10 Q, B. 212, 44 L. J. Q. B. 
 89; Redhead v. Midland By., 1869, L. R. 4 Q. B. 379, 38 
 L. J. Q. B. 169. See Beven, Negligence, 3rd ed. 2, p. 944; 
 Halsbury, Laws of England, s.v. Carriers, 4, p. 44; Leake, Con- 
 tracts, 6th ed. p. 502; Macnamara, Carriers by Land, 2nd ed. 
 p. 577.) 
 
 Whether the fault here is contractual or delictual, and whatever 
 may be the correct view with regard to the onus of proof of fault. 
 in cases of accidents to passengers the reasons against allowing 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 273 
 
 them to discharge their claims beforehand arc very strong. Nor 
 does it seem that the carrier should be allowed to stipulate a 
 restriction of his liability to a certain sum in the event of injury 
 to the passenger. (Josserand, Les Transports, n. 915. Contra, 
 Lyon-Caen et Renault, Trfiite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, 
 n. 716.) Nor, as it seems to me, should it make any difference 
 that the carriage is gratuitous. If the carrier has undertaken to 
 carry the passenger at all he is bound to take care of him. (See 
 Trib. Lyon, 13 janv. 1912, S. 1912. Bull, des Sommaires, 2me 
 partie, 43; Lyon, 28 janv. 1913, S. 1913. Bull, des Sommaires, 
 2me partie, 27; Keq. 18 mars 1912, S. 1913. 1. 430; Rev. Trim. 
 1914, p. 500.) 
 
 And when the owner of animals or goods sent by train is 
 allowed to send his servants with them to take care of them during 
 the transit these servants ought to enjoy the protection given to 
 other passengers. Stipulations that they are to travel at their 
 own risk are against public policy. (See, in this sense, in America 
 the judgment of the Supreme Court of the United States, Rail- 
 road Co.x. Rockwood, 1873, 17 Wall. U.S. 357; Beven, Negli- 
 gence, 3rd ed. 2, p. 956.) 
 
 Different rule in England as to gratuitous passengers. 
 
 But in England it is held that if a passenger contracts to travel 
 at his own risk the company is not liable if he is injured, even 
 though this be the result of their gross negligence. {McCawley 
 v. Furness Rail. Co., 1872, L. R. 8 Q. B. 57, 42 L. J. Q. B. 
 4; Gallin v. L. & N. W. Ry. Co., 1875, L. R. 10 Q. B. 212, 
 44 L. J. Q. B. 89. See Macnamara, Law of Carriers by Land, 
 2nd ed. p. 588; Halsbury, Laics of England, v. Carriers, p. 55.) 
 
 But the carrier of passengers is not allowed to limit his liability 
 for negligence by notice, unless he quotes an alternative rate under 
 which the liability is not limited. (See Clarke v. W. Ham Cor- 
 poration, 1909, 2 K. B. 858, 79 L. J. K. B. 56.) 
 
 Public policy as to carriage of goods. 
 
 In regard to contracts for the carriage of goods the reasons why 
 supervision is necessary are quite different. Common carriers, 
 and more particularly, railway-companies, generally enjoy a 
 monopoly. They are in a position to impose unfair and un- 
 reasonable conditions upon the sender of goods. The sender 
 
 w. — VOL. II. 18 
 
274 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 cannot get his goods to the market except through the instrumen- 
 tality of the railway-company, and the railway-company can say 
 to him " we will carry your goods only upon our conditions, and 
 if you do not choose to accept those, the goods can stay where 
 they are." The sender is in fact in a position of economic in- 
 feriority, and he cannot protect himself. It is in the public 
 interest to secure the transport of commodities upon reasonable 
 terms, and if the senders of goods are coerced by the railway-com- 
 panies to agree to unreasonable terms, they will manage to shift 
 the burden on to the shoulders of the consumers. It is for reasons 
 of this kind that the law regards these contracts with a jealous 
 eye. Even some systems of law, such as the English, which, as a 
 general rule allow the utmost freedom to stipulations of non- 
 liability for fault, apply a different principle to contracts with 
 railway-companies. 
 
 The question ought to be one of reasonableness. 
 
 The correct view of the matter would seem to be that the ques- 
 tion for the court to determine in the particular case is simply 
 whether the clause of non-liability was reasonable in the circum- 
 stances. It is against public order to allow a railway-company 
 to take advantage of a position of economic superiority, and in 
 this way to force the sender of goods to consent to terms to which 
 he would not otherwise have agreed. But if the railway-company 
 offers to the sender a free choice between sending the goods upon 
 ordinary terms, subject to the liability of the railway-company 
 for negligence, or of sending them at reduced rates at his own 
 risk, so that he will have no claim against the railway-company 
 except by proof of del or fmite lourde, and the sender with his eyes 
 open freely accepts the latter alternative, there is no reason of 
 public policy for holding such a stipulation to be void. 
 (Josserand, Les Transports, n. 631; Lyon-Caen et Benault, Traite 
 de Droit Commercial, 4tih ed. 3, n. 626 bis ; Boutaud, Des Clauses 
 de Non-re^ponsabilite, p. 215 and p. 264 and 297; Becque, in Rev. 
 Trim. 1914, p. 318. Cf. C. A. Alex. 16 nov. 1898, B. L. J. 
 XI, 14.) 
 
 English law. 
 
 The English law, as will be explained later, arrives at this 
 result by special legislation. 
 
 9 'MA/* 
 
-STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 275 
 
 Clauses of exoneration in maritime law. 
 
 The validity of clauses in charter parties and bills of Lading 
 excluding the liability of the shipowner for the faults of the 
 captain and crew lias been the subject of much discussion in the 
 French law. The jurisprudence may be now considered as settled 
 in favour of the validity of such clauses. And this conclusion is 
 approved of by the majority of the writers. (Cass. 5 dec. 1910, 
 "S. 1911. 1. 129, and note by M.' Lyon-Caen; Cass. 11 fevr. 
 1908, D. 1908. 1. 214; Sarrut in note to Cass. 9 mars 1886, 
 D. 90. 1. 209; Lyon-Caen et Benault, Traite de Droit Com- 
 mercial, 4th ed. 5, n. 744.) 
 
 The Cour de < 'assation states as the principal reason that the 
 captain and crew of a vessel are, when the vessel is at sea, no longer 
 under the control of the shipowner. (Cass. 14 mars 1877, D. 77. 
 1. 449.) 
 
 The validity of the clause of exoneration here, as already stated, 
 applies even to the dot and jaute lourde of the captain and crew, 
 and the Egyptian courts have followed this rule. (Lyon-Caen 
 et Renault, 5, n. 745 bis; C. A. Alex. 2 avr. 1896, B. L. J. 
 .VIII, 198; C. A. Alex. 19 nov. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 7; C. A. 
 Alex. 31 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 188; C. A. Alex. 9 avril 
 1919, B. L. J. XXXI, 236.) 
 
 The commercial community in France is not satisfied with this 
 state of the law, and there has been a long struggle to make such 
 stipulations unlawful. It has also been proposed to allow the 
 shipowner to exonerate himself from his liability for the f antes 
 nautiques of the captain, i.e., errors of navigation, but not from 
 his liability for fautes commerciales committed by the captain, 
 i.e., faults in loading, stowage, care of cargo and the like. This 
 is the distinction made by the American law and will be referred 
 to later. (Infra, p. 284.) A proposition de loi to that effect 
 was introduced on 10 nov. 1910, by M. Maurice Colin. But ,so 
 far the shipowners have succeeded in preventing an amendment 
 of the law. (See Revue Critique, 1912, p. 124; Lyon-Caen et 
 Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 5, n. 747 bis.) 
 But when the agents of a shipowner are in fact under his control, 
 as, for example, when the ship is in port, and is in charge of the 
 .shipowner or his agent, such clauses of exoneration become in- 
 applicable. (Req. 3 mars 1897, D. 97. 1. 556; Cass. 3 fevr. 
 1904, D. 1905. 1. 315; Lyon-Caen et Renault, 4th ed. 5, n. 745 
 bis; C. A. Alex. 19 nov. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 7.) 
 
 
276 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 And the shipowner cannot stipulate immunity from his own 
 personal fault, and more particularly, he cannot exonerate himself 
 from liability for the unseaworthiness of the ship before its de- 
 parture. (C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 187;. 
 Lyon-Caen et Renault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 5, 
 n. 747.) Nor are such clauses of exoneration from liability for 
 dol or faute lourde valid in cases of contracts for the carriage of 
 goods by river. The French law and the Egyptian law apply 
 different rules for navigation by sea and by inland waterways. 
 The Code of Maritime Commerce applies only to carriage by sea, 
 and the same is true of Book II. of the French Code of Commerce. 
 Both the French Code of Commerce and the Egyptian Code as- 
 similate the carrier by river to the carrier by land. (See C. Com. 
 F. 107; C. Com E. 101/106: Req. 28 feVr. 1900, D. 1900. 1. 
 286.) Subject to what has been said above, clauses of exoneration 
 in maritime law are valid in the case of the carriage of persons 
 as well as in the case of the carriage of goods. 
 
 Laws of other countries. 
 
 In many other countries the validity of clauses of this kind 
 in charter parties and bills of lading is admitted. (See a list of 
 them in Dall. Rep. Pratique, vo. Droit Maritime, n. 950. The 
 English law is stated later.) 
 
 Post-office and telegrams. 
 
 The transmission of letters is managed by a department of the 
 state in Egypt as in imost civilised countries, and, in Egypt, the 
 state likewise conducts the business of sending inland telegrams 
 which in many countries is carried on by private telegraph com- 
 panies. Telegrams from Egypt to foreign countries are sent by 
 private companies. 
 
 Post-office letters. 
 
 As regards the post-office the responsibility of the Egyptian 
 state is greatly limited by the special laws upon the subject. (See 
 Decret du 29 mars 1879 and reglement pour V execution du decret 
 du 29 mars 1879, Lamba, Code Administratis 497; Gelat, Rep. 
 1888, vo. Posies; Trib. civ. Alex. 18 mai 1907, B. L. J. XIX, 
 255.) 
 
 When personal fault can be brought home to an agent or servant 
 of the postal administration he is liable for the damage caused 
 by his fault, and cannot shelter himself behind the law which 
 
 frJAfi.i* f^ 
 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 277 
 
 protects the state from liability. This depends in Egypt upon 
 general principles. In France the distinction is made in the 
 administrative law between fairies cle service and fairies person- 
 nelles, and it is only for the latter that the agent or servant is 
 liable. (See Req. 3 janv. 1876, S. 76. 1. 113, Journal du Palais, 
 76, p. 267; Trib. des Conflits, 8 juin 1907, S. 1909. 3. 134;- 
 Req. 9 mai 1911, D. 1912. 1. 401; Geny, Lettres Missives, 
 .1, p. 112; Hauriou, Droit Administmtif, 8th ed. p. 495.) 
 
 Telegrams sent by private companies. 
 
 The question if a private telegraph-company can validly exone- 
 rate itself from liability does not seem to have arisen in Egypt. 
 It would appear that the same reasons of public policy apply hero 
 as in the case of the common carrier. 
 
 The company is in a position of economic^ superiority which 
 gives it the power to impose unreasonable conditions. If it offers 
 to the sender of a telegram the choice between sending a repeated 
 message for which the company accepts responsibility, or sending 
 an ordinary message at a lower rate at the sender's own risk, this 
 is reasonable enough. But if it exploits its monopoly by declin- 
 ing to send any message which it undertakes to deliver accurately 
 the court should consider such a condition as against public policy. 
 
 It has been held in one case in Quebec that where there is 
 evidence of negligence on the part of a telegraph-company or its 
 employees in the transmission of a message, the company is not 
 protected by a printed condition on the telegraph blank form 
 that it will not be responsible for errors in the transmission of an 
 unrepealed telegram. (Great N. W. Tel. Co. v. Laicrence, R. 
 J. Q. 1 Q. B. 1.) In the United States the authorities are con- 
 flicting. In many states such a condition is in the case of an 
 unrepealed telegram valid. Mr. Cooley sums up the decisions 
 thus: " It is customary for telegraph companies to send messages 
 subject to a condition that they shall not be responsible for errors 
 or delays, unless the message is repeated at the sender's cost. 
 Such conditions have frequently been supported as reasonable < 
 But the condition to be available must be brought to the know- 
 ledge of the party interested in the message, sender or receiver, 
 and in the absence of a provision requiring the message to be 
 repeated, it would be void as an attempt by the company to relieve 
 itself of the consequences of its own fault." (Torts, 3rd ed. 2, 
 p. 1484.) It has been held in some cases that a stipulation was 
 
278 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 invalid by which the liability of the telegraph-company wag 
 limited to a fixed sum. See Hunt v. Railroad, 112 U. S. 331, 
 and cases in Bevi a, Negligetice, 3rd ed. p. 1121.) 
 
 This seems unreasonable. It would appear just to apply the 
 same rules as t<> carriers. If the telegraph-company offers a choice 
 between a cheap message at the sender's risk or a dearer message 
 at the company's risk, what is there in this which is against public 
 policy? 
 
 Telegrams sent by public service. 
 
 The situation is different when the service is in the hands of 
 the state itself. In this case there are special laws excluding or 
 defining the liability of the government. It is no longer a question 
 of stipulation. 
 
 In France by the loi du 29 nov. 1850, VEtat nest soumis a 
 aucune responmhiliU a raison du service de la correspondan 
 privee par la voie telegraphique. (See Panel. Franc, vo. Posies, 
 Telegraphes et Telephones, nos. 1317. 1637. 1640: Geny, Lettres 
 Missives, 1, p. 118.) 
 
 In Egypt there is a Reglement du Service Telegraphique in 
 terms which will be given later. But it is not by any means too 
 clear that this reglement was competently made. 
 
 Egyptian law. 
 
 In the Egyptian law, the question does not seem to have been 
 raised. The State Telegraphs are attached to the Ministry of 
 Public Works, and the Eailway Board is given power to make 
 rules for the management and working of the State Railways and 
 Telegraphs. Loi 25 of 190o, s. 5: Gelat, V. p. 97.) 
 
 That section gives the board power, in particular, to make rules 
 as to various matters. But these are all of an administratis- 
 character, such as defining the powers of the chief officer of the 
 Telegraph Department, prescribing the manner in which accounts 
 shall be kept, and the like. Upon the principle ejusdem generis, 
 it. might be argued that the board has no power under this section 
 to make rules limiting the responsibility of the administration. 
 There does not appear to be any other loi or decret giving such 
 power. From the Annuaire Statistique of 1914, p. 223, it appears 
 that the documents concerning the administration of telegraphs, 
 previous to 1889, have disappeared from the archives. 
 
 The Reglement d>< Si Wit • Telegraphique, printed in the Indiccir 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 279 
 
 teur des Chemins de Far Egyptiens ,1919;, contain- a clause 
 headed Responmbilite which is in those terms:— 
 
 L' Administration n'accepte les depeches que sous la condition 
 expres.se qu'aucune responmbilite ne sera encourue par elle pour 
 les re funis dans lew transmission ou lew distribution. Elle n'est 
 non plus responsable de leur non-transmission ou non-distribution 
 ni d'erreurs (Vune nature ou cause quelconque. 
 
 If the reglement is not competently made, the question has to 
 be considered whether such a condition is against public policy. 
 The state not being protected by special law would be in the sami 
 position as a private company. Upon this basis the clause is 
 unfair and exorbitant. The Egyptian service does not offer the 
 choice to the sender of a telegram either to send a repeated message 
 for which the administration accepts responsibility for errors, or 
 to send an ordinary message at the sender's risk. No such option 
 being offered, and the administration having a monopoly, the 
 clause of exoneration is against public order. 
 
 Contracts by which a workman renounces beforehand his 
 right to claim damages for personal injuries. 
 
 It has been maintained above that it is against jmblic order 
 for a railway-company to limit its liability for accidents to pas- 
 sengers. Similar reasons ought to apply in principle to contracts 
 between an employer and his workman. It is against public order 
 to allow a man to deprive himself by contract of his legal right 
 to safety of life and limb. Life, health and physical safety are 
 not things in commercio. Moreover, in this case also, the employer 
 is usually in a position of economic superiority. The workman 
 who has to earn his bread is practically compelled to agree to 
 unfair provisions. It is for these reasons among others that almost 
 all European countries have now passed laws which not only for- 
 bid stipulations of this kind, but also make the employer respon- 
 sible for accidents caused to the workman in the course of the 
 work without proof of fault on the part of the employed-. (See 
 Sachet, Traite de la Legislation sur les Accidents du Travail : 
 Cabouat, Jules, Traite des Accidents du Travail ; Baudry-Lacant. 
 et Wahl, Louage, 3rd eel. 2, n. 1735 seq.; Colin et Capitant, 2. 
 p. 392; Walton, Workmen's Compensation Act of the Province of 
 Quebec; Boutaud, Clauses de Non-responsabilite, p^ 82 and p. 337 . 
 Cf. Josserand, Les Transports, n. 915; Labbo, Rev. Crit. 1886, 
 p. 448; Trib. de St. Etienne, 10 aoiit 1886, S. 87. 2. 48.) 
 
 
 UuaXt 
 
280 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 In Egypt where there is no legislation like that of the European 
 states, the jurisprudence is much less favourable to the workman. 
 The jurisprudence both in the Native and the Mixed Courts is 
 settled in the sens.- that the risque professionnel falls upon the 
 workman. C. A. 2 dec. 1913, O. B. XV, n. 23; Trib. Civ. 
 Alex. 7 juin 1913. Gaz. Trib. 3, n. 439; C. A. Alex. 1 mai 
 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 269; C. A. Alex. 18 avril 1906, B. L. J, 
 XVIII, 203.) 
 
 The workman cannot succeed without proof of fault on the 
 part of the employer or of some person for whom the employer is 
 
 Monsible. C. A. Alex. 17 mai 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 334.) 
 But a renunciation by the workman beforehand of his right to 
 claim damages is not valid even when the employer undertakes 
 to give the workman rights under a pension scheme. (C. A. 
 Alex. 30 dec. 1908, B. L. J. XXI, 93. Cf. Trib. de Saint- 
 Etienne, 10 aout 1886, S. 87. 2, 48, and the note.) 
 
 Other cases in which advantage has been taken of a position 
 
 of superiority. 
 
 It is possible that the principle followed with regard to con- 
 tracts with carriers may be extended to other cases in which a 
 ' y to the contract has exploited a position of economic superio- 
 rity. According to MM. Colin et Capitant, La clause d'irre- 
 s.ponsabilite est dans certains cas entierement prohibee. wit par 
 la loi, soit par la jurisprudence. Cela a lieu, semble-t-il, lors- 
 qu'il n a entre les cwvtraeUmts une inegalite qui rCa pax permis 
 au creancier <h disouter cette clause avec son. debiteur. (Cows 
 Elementaire, 2, p. 13.) In cpiestions of public policy it is neces- 
 Bary to Lave a wide discretion to the courts. They must be trusted 
 not to apply such a rule except in circumstances of a very >pedal 
 nature. > \ 
 
 In other cases freedom of contract should be allowed. 
 
 If we eliminate the classes of contracts which have been dis- 
 cussed, in all of which there is a risk of one party abusing a 
 position of superiority, there is no reason of public policy for 
 prohibiting clauses of non-responsibility. It is from this point 
 of view immaterial whether the fault which caused the damage 
 was contractual or delictual. And it would make no difference if 
 .\.' adopted tin- doctrine of the r isque cree and treated the fault 
 as purely objective. See Charmont, Les Transformations du 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 281 
 
 'Droit Civil, pp. 233 seq.; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 356; Josserand, 
 Les Transports, n. 883.) Nor should the concurrence of faute 
 contractuelle and faute delictuelle, if it exists, affect the conclu- 
 sion. For, unless the ease falls within one of the exceptiona l 
 
 classes which have heen discussed above, there is no public policy 
 to prevent the parties determining beforehand the indemnity which 
 shall be paid in the event of breach of contract. If they have 
 agreed to substitute a contractual liability for the delictual lia- 
 bility which would exist if there had been no contract, why should 
 their agreement not receive effect? If the contract is lawful in 
 itself the parties may fix as they please the responsibility which 
 will result from its inexecution. Volenti non fit injuria. The 
 failure to perforin the contract does not affect public order, it 
 affects merely the pecuniary interests of the creditor, and if he 
 has chosen to take the risk of the inexecution why should the law 
 be more anxious to protect him than he is to protect himself? 
 As Al. Boutaud well says: La responsabilite delictuelle lors- 
 qu'elle prut faire Vobjet cVun tontrat devient par cela rneme con- 
 tractuelle; il est permis aux interesses a" en determiner librement 
 Vet endue. (Des Clauses cle Non-responsabilite, p. 227; in same 
 sense, Josserand, Les Transport*, n. 628; Saleilles, Theorie 
 Generate de V Obligation, n. 16, and n. 332; Becque, in Rev. 
 Trim. 1914, p. 318.) 
 
 Tendency of recent French jurisprudence. 
 
 It must be admitted that these conclusions are difficult to re- 
 concile with the most recent jurisprudence in France. In several 
 of the latest cases it is laid down in general terms that a party to 
 a contract cannot exonerate himself beforehand from liability for 
 his own fault or the fault of his subordinates, and no distinction 
 is made between faute legere and faute lourde. But these cases 
 must be taken with reference to their particular facts, and it is 
 doubtful if the courts intend to lay down an absolute rule of so 
 general a kind, and so much in conflict with the law as previously 
 understood. The first of these cases was one in which a munici- 
 pality, on the occasion of an industrial exhibition, had induced 
 the exhibitors to sign contracts by which they released the muni- 
 cipality from all liability in the event of damage to the exhibits 
 from fire, accident, theft, etc. The Cow cle Mont pettier decided 
 that the clause was a valid exoneration as regards f aides legere*, 
 and that as regards fautes lourdes it threw the onus of proof upon 
 the exhibitor. The Cow de Cassation appeared to draw no dis- 
 
 ; 
 
282 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 tinction between these two classes of faults, and stated the ride in 
 these terms: Attmcki qu'il n'est pas plus permis de s'exonerer 
 
 (i'lirtii/cr par convention des fautes de ses preposes que de ses 
 propres fautes; que s'il pent m etre autrement cest seidement 
 lorsque le prepose echappe en fait, duns Vcrercice de ses fonctionSj 
 a Vautorite da preposant et a sa direction. (Civ. 31 dee. 1900, 
 D. 1903. 1. 17, S. 1901. 1. 401.;* And the Chambre des Re- 
 quites adopted the same formula in a recent case. (See Rev. 
 Trim. 1912, p. 179. The question there was as to the validity 
 of a clause of exoneration imposed by an information bureau 
 upon its clients. The Agence de Bens&ignements had in that case 
 given information to a client as to the credit and position of a 
 certain individual. This information was highly misleading, and 
 there was gross negligence on the part of the agency in not dis- 
 covering it to be so. The case was undoubtedly one of faute 
 lourde, but the judgment was not rested upon that ground. (Req. 
 27 nov. 1911, D. 1913. 1. 111. See Rev. Trim. 1912, p. 179, 
 and p. 981.) 
 
 The exhibition case just mentioned may perhaps be explained 
 by saying that the court regarded it as one in which one of the 
 parties had abused a superior economic position. As MM. Colin 
 et Capitant put it: La solution serait evidemment excessive si on 
 ne Vexpliquait ici par ce fait que cetait, en realite, la ville qui 
 avait fait la loi des contrats passes avee les exposants. {Cows 
 Elementaire, 2, p. 13. See Rev. Trim. 1914, p. 316.) 
 
 Clauses of non-responsibility in other laws. 
 (1) English law. 
 
 The broad principle of the English law is that a man cannot, 
 claim damages for an injury to which he has consented— Volenti 
 non fit injuria. Before the Workmen's Compensation Act, 1897, 
 the principle was constantly applied in cases of industrial acci- 
 dents. It was not doubted that the workman might accept the 
 risk. {Smith v. Baker, 1891, A. C. 325, 60 L. J. Q. B. 683 . 
 See Beven, Negligence, 3rd ed. 1, p. 646.) The chief limita- 
 tions upon the rule in the English law are, (a) a man cannot by 
 his consent justify an act which is in itself criminal or " un- 
 warrantably dangerous." (See Pollock, Torts, 10th ed. p. 168, 
 and p. 226.) 
 
 (b) Workmen engaged in employments to which the Work- 
 men's Compensation Act, 1906, applies cannot relinquish any 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 283 
 
 right of compensation from the employer for personal injury 
 arising out of and in the course of the employment, excepl in 
 exchange for a scheme of compensation certified as equally bene- 
 ficial. ,6 Edw. 7, c. 58, s. 3.) 
 
 (c) A common carrier may exonerate himself by special con- 
 tract from liability for loss or damage to goods. (The Carriers 
 Aet, 1830 (11 Geo. IV. & 1 Will. IV. c. 68;. See Beven, Negli- 
 gence, 3rd eel. 2, p. 1072.) But in the case of railway and canal 
 companies this freedom is restricted. The company can make 
 such conditions only " as shall be adjudged by the court or judge, 
 before whom any question relating thereto shall be heard, to be 
 just and reasonable." (Railway and Canal Traffic Act, 1854 
 (17 & 18 Vict. c. 31). See Beven, op. tit. 2, p. 925; Macnamara, 
 Can-ins by Land, 2nd ed. p. 152.) The contract must be in 
 writing, and the onus of proof that it is just and reasonable is on 
 the company. {Peek v. North Staffordshire Bij. Co., 1883, 10 
 H. L. C. 473, 32 L. J. Q.-B.-241.) In considering whether a 
 contract is just and reasonable an important element is if the 
 sender had an alternative option of sending the goods upon 
 ordinary terms or at lower rates subject to special conditions. 
 (31 an nhexter, Sheffield cmd Lincolnshire By. Co. v. Brown, 1883, 
 8 A pp. Cas. 703, 53 L. J. Q. B. 124; and see cases cited in 
 Beven, Negligence, p. 929; Macnamara, Carriers by Land, 2nd 
 ed. p. 156.) 
 
 In regard to the carriage of passengers the English law is that 
 a passenger who agrees to travel at his own risk is bound by this 
 stipulation. (Hall v. N. E. By. Co., 1875, L. R. 10 Q. B. 
 437, 44 L. J. Q. B. 164. Cf. Grand Trunk By. v. Robinson, 
 1915, A. C. 740, 84 L. J. P. C. 194, for same rule in Canada.) 
 But the Supreme Court of the United States has held such a 
 stipulation void, and for the reasons stated earlier it seems to be 
 against public policy. (See the cases in Beven, op. cit. 2, p. 956.) 
 
 By the maritime law of England there is nothing to prevent 
 the parties from agreeing that the shipowner shall not be liable 
 even for his own personal fault. An express exception might, 
 for example, relieve the shipowner from his legal duty to provide 
 a seaworthy ship, and that though the unseaworthiness was due to 
 his own negligence. (See Borthwick v. Elderslie Steamship Co., 
 1904, 1 K. B. 324, 74 L. J. K. B. 338; Beven on Negligence, 
 3rd ed. 2, p. 1028.) Such clauses are unusual. On the other hand. 
 English bills of lading commonly relieve the shipowner from the 
 responsibility for the negligence of the captain or crew, and, a 
 
284 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 fortiori, this clause is valid. {The Duero, 1869, L. E. 2A.&E. 
 393, 38 L. J.'Adm. 69; Westport Coal Co. v. McPhail, 1898, 
 2 Q. B. 130, 67 L. J. Q. B. $74; Carver, Carriage of Goods by 
 Sea, 5th ed. s. 101.) 
 
 American law is different. 
 
 Upon this important matter the law of the United States has 
 broken away from the English law. Under the law of the United 
 States by the Federal Act of 1893, commonly known as " The 
 Harter Act," the shipowner is exempted from liability for errors 
 of navigation if he has used due diligence to have the ship sea- 
 worthy and properly equipped. On the other hand, he is not 
 allowed to relieve himself from liability for the negligence of 
 the captain or crew in regard to the loading, stowage, care and 
 delivery of the cargo. (See the Act with a short commentary in 
 Carver, op. tit. n. 103a.) There is legislation on lines closely 
 similar in Australia and Xew Zealand. (See the Acts in Carver, 
 op. til. p. 998.) 
 
 Limitations of liability must be reasonable, and such a clause 
 - this is considered to be unreasonable. 
 
 (2) German law. 
 
 Under the German Code the rule is that the debtor can exonerate 
 himself from any liability except for an intentional act art. 
 276). As regards his preposes, he can even stipulate that he will 
 not be responsible for intentional acts on their part (art. 278. 
 Cosack, Lehrbuch des Deutschen burgerlichen Rechtsjl, 
 p. 346; Saleilles, Theorie Generate cle V Obligation, 3rd eeT p. 
 434). But this wide freedom is to some extent restricted by the 
 article which gives power to the courts to annul contracts by which 
 one part}- has obtained an exorbitant advantage by exploiting the 
 needs, thoughtlessness, or want of experience of the other party. 
 I'ntcr Ausbeutung der Soilage, des Leichtsinm oder der Un&r- 
 fahrenheit tines andern, art. 138; Cosack, 1, p. 232: and see 
 supra, p. 30-5.) 
 
 In the German law the compulsory insurance of workmen 
 against industrial accidents invalidates all stipulations of non- 
 liabilitv. See Boutaud, Des Clauses de A 'on-responsabilite, p. 
 343.) * 
 
 In regard to railways the German legislation is somewhat com- 
 plicated. The company may limit its liability by certain stipu- 
 
STIPULATIONS OF EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY. 285 
 
 lations, but cannot exonerate itself altogether. (See for details, 
 Thaller, Ann-ales de Droit Commercial, 1, p. 37. Cf. Boutaud. 
 op. fit. p. 307.) 
 
 (3) Swiss law. 
 
 The Federal Code of Obligations contains two articles which 
 deal carefully with clauses of exoneration, and by special laws 
 railway companies, steamship companies, and manufacturers are 
 not allowed to exonerate themselves even from the ordinary negli- 
 gence — fante legere — of their employees. (See art. 3, Loi federate 
 sur la responsabilite des Chemins de fer et bateaux a vapeur, du 
 ler juillet, 1875; art. 4 du loi federate du 29 mars 1893, sur les 
 transports par chemins de fer et bateaux a vapeur; art. ler, loi 
 federate du 25 juin 1881, sur la responsabilite des fabrieants : 
 Boutaud, Des Clauses de Non-responsabilite, p. 309 and p. 343.) 
 
 The general articles upon the subject are as follows: — 
 
 Est nulle toute stipulation tendant a liberer davanoe le debiteur 
 de la responsabilite qu'il encourrait en cas de dot ou de faute grave. 
 
 Le juge peut, en vertu de son pouvoir d appreciation, tenir pour 
 nulle une clause qui libererait davance le debiteur de toute re- 
 sponsabilite en cas de faute legere, si le creancier, au moment ou 
 il a renonce a rechercher le debiteur, se trouvait a son service, ou 
 si la responsabilite resulte de Vexercice dune Industrie concedee 
 par Vautorite. Les regies partieulieres du contrat d 'assurance de- 
 meurent reservees. (Code Fed. Obi. art. 100.) Under the in- 
 dustries concedees fall raiiwaj^s and steamships, and certain pro- 
 fessions such as those of notary, advocate, innkeeper. 
 
 Celui qui, meme d'une maniere licite, confie a des auxiliaires, 
 tels que des personnes vivant en metiage avec lui ou des employes, 
 le soin dexecuter une obligation ou d'exercer un droit derivant 
 dune obligation, est responsable envers V autre partie du dommage 
 qu'ils causent dans V accomplissement de lew travail. 
 
 JJne convention prealable pent exclure en tout ou en partie I ■ 
 responsabilite derivant du fait des auxiliaires. 
 
 Si le creancier est au service du debiteur, ou si la responsabilite 
 resulte de Vexercice dune Industrie concedee par Vautorite, le 
 debiteur ne peut s'exonerer wnventionnellement que de laresponsa- 
 bilite deemdant dune faute legiere (art. 101. ' See Rossel et 
 Mentha, Droit Civil Suisse. 3. p. 132 
 
286 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XVI. 
 
 NON-PERFORMANCE OF CONTRACT WITHOUT 
 FAULT OF DEBTOR. 
 
 (1) Exceptional cases. 
 (a) Express stipulation of warranty. 
 
 It may appear from the terms of the contract that the debtor 
 guaranteed its performance, in the sense that he bound himself to 
 pay the damages in the event of non-performance, whether this 
 non-performance was due to his fault or not'. 
 
 The validity of such a stipulation is recognised in many articles 
 of the French Code. (C. C. F. 1302, al. 2, 1772, 1825; C. C. E. 
 -393/480; Eeq. 31 oct. 1905, D. 1907. 1. 38; Aubry et Ran, 5th 
 (1. 4, p. 169; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 463; D. X. C. C. 
 art. 1148, nos. 33 seq. ; C. A. Alex. 5 fevr. 1918, B. L. J. XXX, 
 209.) Such clauses, upon general principles, will be construed in 
 favour of the debtor if their interpretation is doubtful. 
 
 Conversely, by the contract the debtor may have exonerated 
 himself from his liability for n on -performance even caused by, 
 his fault, unless the case is one in which, upon the principles 
 explained earlier, such a stipulation must be considered as against 
 public policy. 
 
 (b) Implied warranty. 
 
 There are cases in which the courts will hold that without any 
 xpress clause to that effect the debtor has undertaken to be re- 
 sponsible for all risks. If, for example, a contract is made at a 
 time 'when a war is on the point of breaking out, it may Veil appear 
 that the parties took this risk into consideration, and that the 
 debtor undertook to perform his contract whether the war broke 
 out or not. Trib. Com. de la Seine, 10 oct. 1894, Journ. Droit 
 International Prive, 1895, p. 108; Wahl, A., in Rev. Trim 1915 
 p. 384.) 
 
 
 . 
 
 i^Aru 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 287 
 
 Some French writers contend that apart from express stipula- 
 tion the debtor can in no case be bound without fault. (B.-L. et 
 Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 463.) 
 
 But the code does not say so, and there is no reason why in this 
 case, as in others, the court should not give effect to the true 
 intention of the parties. (Planiol, 2, n. 233.) 
 
 (c) Warranty of carrier and hotel-keeper against theft. 
 
 Moreover, as will be explained later, the carrier and the hotel- 
 keeper are subject to a special liability in regard to loss by theft 
 of goods entrusted to them. 
 
 (2) General rule that damages are due. 
 
 Apart from these classes of cases the rules are — 
 
 (1) That the. debtor is liable to pay damages for non-perform- 
 ance due to his fault. 
 
 (2) That the debtor is relieved from his liability to pay damages 
 . if he prove that the non-performance was due to a cause for which 
 
 he was not responsible. 
 
 Supervening impossibility of performance. 
 
 The defence here is that a supervening cause, not imputable 
 to the debtor, which has occurred after the date of the contract 
 has prevented its performance. The case where the performance 
 was impossible ab initio has been explained under the head of the 
 object of obligations. {Supra, I, p. 78.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code states the rule thus: — 
 
 'Damages, as apart from restitution, are not recoverable for 
 entire or partial non-performtmce or for delay in performance, 
 unless such non-performance or delay is due to the fault of the 
 debtor. (C. C. E. 119/177. Cf. C. C. E. 178/241. See C. A. 
 Alex. 13 dec. 1916, B. L. J. XXIX, 107.) 
 
 The French Code has two articles on the subject: — 
 
 Le debiteur est condamne, s'il y a lieu, au payement de dorrt- 
 ■mages et interets, soit draison de Vinexecution de V obligation, soil 
 a raison du retard dans I 'execution, toutes les fois qu'il ne justifie 
 pas que V inexecution provient d'une cause etrangere qui ne peut 
 lui etre imputee, encore qu'il ny ait aucune mauvaise foi de sa 
 part. 
 
 
 ■■ (i j 
 
288 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 11 n'y a lieu a aucuns dom mages et interets lorsque, par suite 
 
 dVune force majeure ou d'un can fortuit, le debit air a ete empeche 
 de donner ou de faire ce a quoi il etait oblige, ou a fait ce qui 
 lui etait interdit (arts. 1147, 1148). 
 
 The French Code contains no definition of either cas fortuit, or 
 force -majeure, but it is clear, reading the two articles together, that 
 the legislator meant to comprise under these terms collectively 
 all the causes, known and unknown, which have prevented the 
 performance of the obligation without fault on the part of the 
 debtor. 
 
 Fault and inevitable accident between them embrace every pos- 
 sible cause of innocent non-performance. Where fault ends 
 fortuitous event begins. (Of. Saleilles, Theorie Generate de 
 V Obligation, n. 24.) M. Josserand disputes this. He says, II 
 existe des causes d'iriex edition qui ne sont nullement imputable 
 au debiteur, et qui ne rentrent cependant pas dans la notion de 
 la force majeure ni dans celle du cas fortuit, a savoir, pour le 
 contrat de transport, le vice propre de la marchmdise. et le fait So 
 Vexpediteur ou du destmataire : la force majeure et le cas fortuit 
 nepuisent done pas tout le domaine de la non-re sponsabilite : its 
 ne sont pas, a &ux seuls, toutes les causes d- exoneration . (Les 
 Transports, n. 571.) 
 
 But this does not appear to be a sound view of the matter. It 
 is a term of the contract of carriage that the carrier is not held to 
 warranty against loss or damage to the goods caused by inherent 
 defects in them, or by the fault or negligence of the consignor/ 
 (See C. Comm. F. 103; C. Comm. E. 97/102; Josserand, op. cit. 
 n. 609.) The carrier never undertook the safe delivery of goods 
 in these circumstances, and there is, therefore, no failure on his 
 part to perform what he has promised. 
 
 The two expressions, force majeure and cas fortuit, employed in 
 article 1148 are meant to correspond to the single term of article 
 
 1147, cause etrangere qui ne pent etre imputee au debiteur. It is 
 not easy to draw any clear line of distinction between cas fortuit 
 and force majeure, but, fortunately, this is not important, because 
 the legal effect is the same whether we consider the case as falling 
 under the one designation or the other. Aubry et Kau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 167; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 455; D. X. C. C. art. 
 
 1148, n. 2.) It is important to emphasise this point, because, 
 as will be shown presently, attempts have been made recently to 
 prove that force majeure and cas fortuit do not produce the same 
 leo-al effects. (See Josserand, Les Transports, n. 568, for the 
 
 £=*•• ■ ■' 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 289 
 
 bibliography. Cf. Salcilles, Theorie Generate de V Obligation, 
 n. 24.) Some modern codes express the rule by saying* that the 
 debtor is excused if he proves that the breach of contract is due to< 
 a cause not imputable to him, and they avoid using such terms as 
 force majeure and cas fortuit. (Swiss Federal Code of Obliga- 
 tions, art. 97; German Code, art. 275. See infra, p. 318.) 
 
 Other codes use these terms and attempt to define them. 
 
 Thus, the Spanish Code says: — 
 
 Bors des cas expressement jndiques pur la hi, et de ceux ou 
 V obligation le stipule ainsi, mil ne repondra des evenements qu'il 
 ria pu prevmr, ou qui, bien que prevus, ont ete inevitables (art. 
 1105). Arid that code, though in several articles it uses the term 
 cas fortuit, does not seem to employ the expression force majeure 
 at all. (See arts. 1096, 1183, 1488, 1575.) 
 
 The Code of Quebec sometimes speaks of cas fortuit alone, some- 
 times of cas fortuit or force Majeure, and sometimes of force 
 majeure alone, and it is clear that the legislator uses the two terms 
 indifferently. (See arts. 1050, 1072, 1650, 1767, 1768, 1815; 
 Mignault, Droit Civil Canadien, 5, p. 660.) And that code com- 
 bines cas fortuit and force majeure in a common definition. 
 
 A fortuitous event is one which is unforeseen and caused by 
 superior force which it was impossible to resist (art. 17, n. 24). 
 
 The latest code, that of Morocco, which came into force on 
 15 October, 1913, states the French law in a more satisfactory way;. 
 
 II n'y a lieu a aucuns dommages-interets, lorsque le debiteur 
 juslifie que V inexecution ou le retwd proviennent d'une cause 
 qui ne peut lui etre imputee, telle que la force majeure, le cas 
 fortuit ou la demeure du creamier. 
 
 La force majeure est tout fait que Vhomme ne peut prevenir, 
 tel que les phenomenes naturels (inondations, secher esses, orages, 
 incendies, sauterelles), V invasion ennemie, le fait du prince, et qui 
 rend impossible V execution de V obligation. 
 
 N'est point consideree comme force majeure la cause qu'il etait 
 possible d'eviter, si le debiteur ne justifie qu'il a deploy e toute 
 diligence pour s'en premunir. 
 
 N'est pas egalement consideree comme force majeure la cause 
 qui a ete occasionnee par une faute precedente du debiteur. (Dahir 
 formant Code des Obligations, arts. 268, 269.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code avoids using either of the terms force 
 majeure or cas fortuit in the general article as to liability for 
 breach of contract. (C. C. E. 119/177.) In other articles it em- 
 
 w.— VOL. II. 19 
 
290 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ploys both terms, though force majeure does not occur so often as 
 cas fortnit. (See arts. 342 427, 489/598, for force majeure; and 
 for cas jortuit (arts. 23/42, 218 283, 392/479, 417/509. 544/666, 
 562/686.) 
 
 In one article any accidental circumstance— toute circonstance 
 fortuite—is used as equivalent arts. 411/502). 
 
 In the French and Egyptian codes it is plain that the legislator 
 uses the terms cas jortuit and force majeure as equivalent, and 
 does not attempt to make any distinction between them. (Demo- 
 lombe, 24, n. 553; Baudry-Laeant. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n, 455; 
 Planiol,2, n. 231; D. N. C. 0. art. 1148, n. 3.) 
 
 And the jurisprudence applies to the same facts sometimes the 
 name of cas jortuit and sometimes that of force majeure. (See 
 Paris, 13 now 1903, D. 1904. 2. 73, and Dissertation by M. 
 Colin.) 
 
 Some writers consider that as a matter of correct language the 
 term cas jortuit is more appropriate to denote the action of natural 
 forces, such as fire and flood, while force majeure is more properly 
 applied to an act of man which creates an insurmountable obstacle 
 to the performance. fHuc, 7, n. 143.) Other distinctions have 
 been suggested, but there is no great value in them. 
 
 Force majeure in law of responsibility and in law of 
 prescription. 
 
 It is not only when the debtor in a contract claims to be 
 exonerated from the consequences of-iiis non-performance that the 
 question arises what amounts to force majeure. The same ques- 
 tion comes up when a defendant in an action of responsibility 
 maintains that the accident was caused by force majeure, and also 
 when a party pleads that his right to sue has not been lost by 
 prescription because he was prevented from suing by force majeure. 
 (Sec infra, p. 555.) 
 
 Cas fortuit and force majeure include both objective 
 impossibility and subjective impossibility. 
 
 The impossibility of performance may be either an absolute or 
 objective impossibility, that is to say, it is impossible for any one 
 at all to perform the obligation; or it may be a relative or sub- 
 jective impossibility, that is to say, it is impossible for the debtor 
 .(- perform the obligation, but it might be performed by another.. 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 29] 
 
 If, for example, the debtor was bound to deliver a ship, and the 
 ship was torpedoed by a submarine and sunk, there would be ail 
 absolute impossibility. If, on the other hand, the debtor's duty 
 was to deliver a diamond, and the diamond was stolen by X, there 
 is a relative impossibility, because, although the debtor cannot 
 perform his obligation, it might be performed by X. 
 
 The German Code is careful to use different words to denote 
 these two kinds of impossibility. It calls objective impossibility 
 ZJnmoglichkeit, and relative impossibility Unvermpgen des 
 Schuldners zur Leistung. ^German Code. arts. 275, 279; Cosack, 
 Lshrbuch des Deutschen bilrgerlichen Rechts, 6th ed. 1, p. 394; 
 Windscheid, Pandekten, 8th ed. 2, s. 264.) 
 
 In the French law the impossibility which is created by cas 
 fortuit or force majeure is sometimes objective and sometimes 
 •subjective. 
 
 Attempted distinction between the legal effects of force 
 majeure and those of cas fortuit. 
 
 Some modern French writers attempt to make a distinction 
 between the legal effects of force majeure and of cas fortuit re- 
 spectively, more particularly in the contract of carriage of goods. 
 They contend that it is only loss or damage caused by force 
 majeure which the carrier does not have to make good. He is 
 responsible for the loss or damage caused by cas fortuit. 
 [Dissertation by M. A. Colin, in note to Paris, 13 nov. 1903, 
 D. 1904. 2. 73; Thaller, Traite EUmentaire de Droit Commercial, 
 4th ed. n. 1198; Josserand, Les Transports, nos. 570 seq. Contra, 
 Lyon-Caen et Benault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 3, 
 n. 598; Sarrut, Transport des marchandises, n. 751. See D. N. 
 C. C. Additions, 1913, art. 1148, nos. 1 seq.) 
 
 The chief arguments advanced in support of the new theory are 
 the following: — 
 
 (1) The tendency of the law is to abandon more and more the 
 old theory that there is no liability without fault actual or pre- 
 sumed. Liability is now admitted in many cases on the mere 
 ground that the person who for his profit creates a risk is bound 
 by law to compensate those who suffer damage thereby caused. 
 
 This theory, commonly called la theorie du risque cree, underlies 
 the French legislation for workmen's compensation for accidents 
 (Loi du 9 avril 1898), and it underlies also the jurisprudence 
 
 19 (2) 
 

 292 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 which makes a man liable without proof of personal fault for the 
 damage caused by an animal or by an inanimate thing which 
 belongs to him. Fault in the legal sense is becoming more and 
 more°an objective fact, for the estimation of which any inquiry 
 into the mind, intention, or moral condition of the author of the 
 wrong is irrelevant. The discussion of this doctrine belongs to. 
 the subject of Responsibility. 
 
 When the execution of an obligation is prevented by the happen- 
 ing of an event which the debtor was powerless to prevent, and 
 against the occurrence of which he could not have provided, this 
 fact does not in itself liberate him from his duty to pay damages, 
 for the accident may be due to a risk which the debtor has 
 
 created. 
 
 If an explosion takes place in a factory, or a railway embank- 
 ment slips. down, or the splitting of a rail causes a train to go 
 off the line, these are accidents inherent in the enterprise. They 
 are fortuitous events, if you will, but that is no reason why the 
 person for whose profit the enterprise is conducted should not 
 pay for them. It is, according to the writers above referred to, 
 only to accidents of this kind arising out of the enterprise carried 
 on for the debtor's profit that the law applies the term cos 
 fort nit. 
 
 (2) For6e majeure is something quite different; it is always a 
 force operating from without. It is caused by a risk which the 
 debtor has in no way created. The failure by the debtor to per- 
 form his obligation is due to a foreign cause, to what the French 
 Code describes as a cause etrangere qui ne pent lui etre imputee. 
 (C. C. F. 1147.) An earthquake, a flood, or a fire caused by 
 lightning are examples of the operation of the forces of nature 
 which may, according to circumstances, amount to force majeure. 
 They axe not necessarily so, for it may appear from the circum- 
 stances that they ought to have been provided against, and as to 
 fire caused by lightning, the character of the enterprise may have 
 increased the danger from lightning. So, likewise, the act of 
 man, such as an invasion of an enemy, the interference by the 
 sovereign {fait du prince), the theft by a third party of a thing 
 to be delivered, and so on, may be proved to be force majeure. 
 (See infra, pp. 298 seq.) 
 
 The criterion between cas fort u it and force majeure is found by 
 asking the question, was the accident caused by a risk which was 
 inherent in the enterprise or by a risk which was external to it? 
 (See B.-L. et Barde. Oblig. 4, n. 2972. y, and authorities in pre- 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 293 
 
 ceding note. Cf. in the German law, Cosack, Lehrbueh des 
 'Deutschen biirgerlichen Rechts, 6th ed. 1, p. 291.) 
 
 Criticism of new theory. 
 
 From the legislative standpoint there is something to be said 
 for this new theory, but as an interpretation of the codes it is 
 entirely unsound. It has not prevailed in the jurisprudence. 
 (See Req. 31 oct. 1905, D. 1907. 1. 38, note 1.) It is hopeless 
 to attempt to show that the French Code makes a distinction 
 between cm fortuit and force majeure, and the argument based 
 on the expression came etrangere in C. C. F. 1147 is not avail- 
 able in Egypt or in the Province of Quebec, where the codes do 
 not use that expression at all. (C. C. E. 119/177; C. C. Q. 
 1071.) 
 
 Accordingly, in the Egyptian law as it stands, this theory must 
 be absolutely rejected. 
 
 Essential characteristics of fortuitous event. 
 
 It is convenient to use the term "fortuitous event" to denote 
 the cause sometimes called cas fortuit, sometimes called force 
 majeure, which has prevented the performance of the obligation. 
 If it is to liberate the debtor it must always possess three qualities: 
 
 (1) It must not be imputable to the debtor; 
 
 (2) It must have been impossible to foresee; 
 
 (3) It must have been impossible to prevent. 
 
 These characteristics indicated by the Roman law have been 
 consistently regarded as the marks of a fortuitous event. Omnem 
 vim cui resisti non potest. (Dig. 19. 2. 15. 2.) Quce fortuitis 
 casibus accidunt, cum prcevideri non potuerant. (Code, 4. 24. 6.) 
 
 So the Spanish Code says: — 
 
 Hors des cas expressement indiques par la lot, et de ceux oil 
 V obligation le stipule ainsi, nul ne repondra des evenements qiCil 
 ria pu prevoir, ou qui, bien que prevus, ont ete inevitables. (Code, 
 Espagnol, 1105; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 455; C. A. Alex. 
 20 dec. 1890, B. L. J. XII, 51; C. A. Alex. 8 fevr. 1911, 
 B. L. J. XXIII, 159.) 
 
 >-.- j . j - ■ ■ 
 
294 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Event founded upon as force majeure must not have been 
 brought about by any act of the debtor. 
 
 The debtor will not be excused by proof of a fortuitous event 
 unless the fortuitous event was the sole cause of the non-per- 
 formance. If the event itself was due to tlie fault of the debtor 
 he cannot found upon it as an excuse. (B.-L. et Barde, Ohlig. 
 3, n. 1920, b; Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 184; Josserand, Les Trans- 
 ports, n. 601, 898. 
 
 Nor can the debtor defend himself successfully by the plea of 
 force majeure if the fact upon which he founds as an excuse was 
 brought about at his own request or by his own act, although that 
 act was not wrongful. (B.-L. et Barde, OlMig. 1, n. 462; Larom- 
 biere, art. 1148, n. 21; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, n. 31.) 
 So it was held that a railway-company could not relieve itself 
 from certain obligations upon the plea that its system had been 
 bought by the state, when the fact was that the railway-company 
 had not been expropriated against its will but had solicited the 
 expropriation and freely consented to it. (Cass. 18 avril 1888, 
 D. 84. 1. 25. Cf. Paris, 8 juin 1899, D. 99. 2. 477.) 
 
 And so it would appear that an employer of labour cannot 
 found upon a strike as being force majeure, when the strike was 
 brought about by his own fault in not treating his employees 
 fairly. (Req. 28 oot. 1907, D. 1909. 1. 282. See infra, p. 314.) 
 
 So, bankruptcy is not in itself a fortuitous event, being in fact 
 commonly due to causes over which the victim has some control. 
 In order to excuse himself on this ground from the execution of 
 his contract the debtor would need to prove, not only that he was 
 bankrupt, but also that his bankruptcy was brought about by 
 force majeure, that is to say, by causes which he could not have 
 prevented or avoided. (Alger, 2 dec. 1850, D. 54. 5. 373; Rouen, 
 27 aout 1873, D. 76. 2. 62; Paris, 17 fevr. 1892, D. 94. 2. 1, 
 and note by M. Boistel; C. A. Alex. 27 dec. 1899, B. L. J. 
 XII. 53.) 
 
 Event must be impossible to foresee. 
 
 If the event is one which might have been anticipated and 
 guarded against by taking due precautions,, the debtor who neglects 
 these precautions is not liberated. 
 
 A French post-office official had charge of securities which were 
 in course of transit. The value of the securities had been declared 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 295 
 
 by tin 1 sender, and in this case the French law makes the adminis- 
 tration liable for their loss up to their declared value but not 
 exceeding- 10,000 francs. (Loi da 25 avril 1873, art. 10; 
 Josser and, Les Transports, p. 692.) 
 
 The intervention of force majeure, however, liberates the 
 administration. 
 
 In this case the official had received warnings that an attempt 
 to rob him had been concerted, but he took no special precautions, 
 and he was, in fact, robbed of the securities by armed robbers. 
 The Coiir d'Aix held that in these circumstances the robbery by 
 an armed force did not amount to force majeure. (Aix, 20 dec. 
 1909. See Kev. Trim. 1910, p. 440.) The Cour de Cassation 
 rejected a ponrvoi against this judgment. (Cass. 9 mai 1911, S. 
 1911. 1. 576, D. 1911. 1. 401; Rev. Trim. 1912, p. 188. Cf. 
 Rev. Trim. 1913, p. 820.) And when the obligation is to pay a 
 sum of money the sudden illness of the debtor is not force majeure. 
 La maladie pouvant et devant etre prevue ne petit constituer mi cas 
 de force majeure en mature de payement. (Req. 15 juin 1911, 
 D. 1912. 1. 181, and infra, p. 302.) 
 
 For similar reasons, the vendor of an immoveable who suffers 
 an eviction which prevents his execution of the sale cannot escape 
 liability to pay a penalty stipulated for non-execution by plead- 
 ing that, the eviction was force majeure. (C. A. iUex. 14 mai 
 1908, B. L. J. XX, 220.) 
 
 A recent French case is a good illustration of the principle. 
 An electric light- and power-company stipulated in its contracts 
 with its customers that it would not be liable for temporary 
 interruption of the current when that was caused by force majeure 
 or by public works. Work was begun by a railway contractor 
 in the immediate proximity of the electric cable belonging to the 
 company. There was a probability that in the course of this 
 work the cable would be cut or damaged, and this in fact 
 happened. It was held that the electric-company in these 
 circumstances was not liberated: — 
 
 Qucmd ce.s travaux, dont Vexecution etait prevue depuis long- 
 temps, out exige le deplacement du cable de la compagnie, laquelle 
 devait done prevoir les consequences desdits travaux et prendre 
 toutes mesures utiles pour ev'iter les accidents, ce qu'elle n'a pas 
 fait. (Req. 23 avril 1901, D. 1903. 1. 347.) 
 
296 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Impossibility must be absolute. 
 
 The debtor cannot liberate himself upon the ground of force 
 majeure unless there is an absolute impossibility in the execution 
 of the obligation. It is not enough that in consequence of the 
 fortuitous event the execution has become more difficult or more 
 onerous, nor is the debtor excused when the impossibility is merely 
 because he miscalculated his own powers and promised to do some- 
 thing which is beyond his strength. B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, 
 n. 408; Planiol, 2, n. 232; B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 1, n. 376; 
 Req. 3 mai 1909, D. 1909. 1. 315; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, 
 n. 23, and art. 1126, n. 40; Cons. d'Etat, 9 dec. 1887, D. 88. 5. 
 497; Cass. 16 juin 1900, D. 1905. 1. 336; Req. 27 oct. 1908, 
 D. 1910. 1. 311; Cass. 4 aout 1915, D. 1916. 1. 22; Conseil 
 d'Etat, 30 mars 1916, D. 1916. 3. 25; Taris, 21 dec. 1916, D. 
 1917. 2. 33, and note by M. Capitant; C. A. Alex. 20 juin 
 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 335; C. A. Alex. 8 fevr. 1911, B. L. J. 
 XXIII, 159; C. A. Alex. 7 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 416; 
 C. A. Alex. 17 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 157. As to the 
 possibility of reducing the damages when there is no absolute 
 impossibility of performance, see infra, War as Force majeure, 
 p. 307.) 
 
 The impossibility must continue. 
 
 Force majeure is only an excuse so long as it lasts. If the 
 impediment is merely temporary the execution of the obligation 
 is suspended until the impediment is removed. (Cass. 15 fevr. 
 1888, D. 88. 1. 203. See infra, under War as force majeure, 
 pp. 307 seq.) 
 
 Debtor who foresees the inexecution must do his best to 
 minimise its effects. 
 
 The debtor who wishes to excuse himself on the plea of 
 
 fortuitous event must show that he did his best to minimise its 
 
 • fleets and to do the most that was possible in the circumstances. 
 
 Req. 28 avr. 1901, D. 1903. 1. 347; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, 
 
 n. 26.) 
 
 If, after the date of the contract, the debtor foresees that he 
 will be prevented by a fortuitous event from its execution, ho 
 must do his best to cause his creditor as little loss as possible. 
 
 So, when a man had sold a future crop of cotton' calculated to 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 297 
 
 be so many kantars and he saw that the crop, owing to natural 
 causes, was going to be much less, it was held that he was bound 
 to notify his creditor without delay so that the damage to him 
 would be as small as possible. (C. A. Alex. 1 mars 1905, 
 B. L. J. XVII, 138.) 
 
 So there may be circumstances in which a carrier whose vessel 
 cannot proceed on account of a high flood in a river is bound to 
 send the goods by railway. (See Cass. 6 juin 1900, D. 1905. 
 1. 336.) 
 
 Debtor not bound to take an altogether unusual precaution. 
 
 On the other hand, in saying that the fortuitous event must be 
 something impossible to resist or to provide against, it is not 
 meant that the debtor must take precautions of an altogether 
 unusual kind. He must take all ordinary precautions such as 
 might be expected to be contemplated by the parties. If, after 
 doing so, he is prevented from performing his contract he will 
 be excused. 
 
 So, for example, where the contract is to supply water or gas 
 by means of pipes, the natural sinking of the ground may cause 
 a breaking of pipes and prevent the fulfilment of a contract, 
 and, if so, the debtor who is thus prevented will be excused if 
 he took ordinary precautions, taking into account the nature of 
 the ground. (Sce.C. A. Alex. 28 fevr. 1896, B. L. J. VIII, 
 322; C. A. Alex. 28 mars 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 221.) 
 
 Engineering skill might devise means of preventing such a 
 subsidence, but, if to do so would require measures altogether 
 unusual, the subsidence will be considered to be fortuitous as far 
 as the debtor is concerned. So, where provision is made for such 
 natural events as floods, a flood of an altogether exceptional 
 character may be regarded as a fortuitous event. -Thus in a 
 Canadian case, where a cellar had been flooded owing to the fact 
 that a sewer was not large enough to carry off the water during 
 an altogether exceptional storm of rain, it was held in an action 
 of damages that the loss was caused by a fortuitous event. 
 (Faulkner v. City of Ottawa, 1909, 41 Canadian Supreme Court 
 Reports, 190.) 
 
 It may be said that even a very unusual storm or a very high 
 flood can be anticipated, because such events do occur at rare 
 intervals, but, though this is true, the debtor will not in most 
 cases be expected to anticipate events so unusual. 
 
298 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Force majeure a question of fact. 
 
 The question whether the debtor who pleads that he is liberated 
 by force majeure has made out that defence is eminently one of 
 appreciation. It is for the court to decide it upon considera- 
 tion of the particular facts proved. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, 
 n. 456; Aubry et Kau, 5th eel. 4, p. 168, note 35 bis; Req. 
 22 oct. 1895, D. 96. 1. 72: D. N. C. C. art. 1148, n. 45.) 
 
 The defence may be pleaded either in an action to enforce the 
 performance of contract or in an action of damages for its non- 
 performance. 
 
 Illustrations of force majeure, 
 (a) Events due to the forces of nature. 
 
 Ordinary climatic conditions such as may be expected to occur 
 will not as a general rule be regarded as fortuitous events. It 
 is true that they cannot be prevented, but they can be foreseen and 
 provided against. (See Larombiere, art. 1148, n. 4; Panel. 
 Franc, vo. Oblig. n. 1900.) The parties when they made their 
 contract had these conditions in mind. How far wind, rain, 
 frost, floods, and so forth, are ordinary conditions depends on 
 the particular locality. Frost in Egypt of fifty degrees below- 
 zero Centigrade, if it prevented the performance of a contract, 
 would undoubtedly be force majeure, whereas in certain parts of 
 Canada it would be an event to be expected at some seasons. 
 Floods occur in some rivers with remarkable regularity, whereas 
 in other rivers they are quite exceptional. Earthquakes, light- 
 ning, and shipwreck are events which in many cases may be force 
 majeure, but they are not necessarily to be so considered. 
 
 The earthquake might be in a place where earthquakes are 
 frequent, as for example in Japan, and it might have been jDOssible 
 by taking precautions to perform the contract in spite of the 
 earthquake . 
 
 The shipwreck might not have hapj>ened in spite of the storm, 
 but for faulty navigation on the part of the captain for whom 
 the debtor was responsible. (See Pau, 9 juill. 1872, D. 74. 2. 
 193.) 
 
 Lightning is generally a fortuitous event, but it may not be 
 so when the defendant has increased the risk of lightning. 
 
 Electric installation^ of some kind may have attracted the 
 lightning. 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 29f> 
 
 A fortiori, the rise and fall of many rivers being' a thing to 
 bo calculated upon, precautions might have been taken which would 
 have ensured the performance of the obligation. See Lyon, 
 22 juin 1855, D. 56. 2. 2; Rev. Trim. 191-3. p. 820. 
 
 Destruction of specific thing to be delivered. 
 
 The important case where the performance of the obligation is 
 rendered impossible by the destruction of a specific thing which 
 the debtor was bound to deliver will be explained later in the 
 chapter upon the extinction of obligations. It is true that this 
 is only an illustration of the general rules applying to force 
 majeure, but the French Code deals separately with the perte de 
 la chose due, and it is perhaps more convenient to follow this order. 
 (C. C. F. 1302.) 
 
 Alteration of physical conditions rendering performance 
 
 impossible. 
 
 It may be a part of the contract that the obligation is to be 
 performed in a certain place. From a cause not imputable to 
 the debtor this place is destroyed or put into such a state that 
 performance becomes impossible. For example, a workman is 
 engaged to paint a house and the house falls down or is destroyed 
 by fire before the work begins. In such a ease the other party is 
 liberated. (Dall. Rep. Louage d'Oavrage, n. 69; B.-L. et Wahl, 
 Louage, 3rd ed. 2, n. 2902; D. N. C. C. art. 1780. n. 559. Cf. 
 for same rule in the English law, Taylor v. Caldwell, 1863, 3 
 B. & S. 826, 32 L. J. Q. B. 164, 129 R. R. 573. See Pollock, 
 Contracts, 8th ed. p. 437, and infra, p. 321, for cases in which 
 the principle of Taylor' v. Caldwell has been extended.) 
 
 Fire as force majeure. 
 
 A fire which prevents the execution of an obligation by causing 
 the destruction of the thing to be delivered, or in some other way. 
 is not necessarily a fortuitous event, because the fire may have been 
 caused by the fault of the debtor or that of his servants. It is 
 not enough for the debtor to prove that he was prevented by a 
 fire from fulfilling his obligation; he must prove in addition that 
 the fire was not caused by his fault or that of persons for whom 
 he is responsible. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3. n. 1923: 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4. p. 196. note 36.) 
 
 L'incendie nest pas par lui-meme mi cas de force majeure. 
 
300 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 11 n'y a force majeure, que si le debiteur n'a commis auciine 
 faute, aucune imprudence ou negligence, s'il rta pu ni prevoir 
 ni conjurer Vevenement. (Cass. 27 et 28 oct. 1913, D. 1916. 1. 
 85.) 
 
 The exact nature of the proof which the debtor must make in 
 order to exonerate himself has been the subject of much contro- 
 versy. Does he need to prove positively how the fire originated 
 in order to exclude the idea of his own fault, or is it enough for 
 him to prove that he took all reasonable precautions and that the 
 origin of the fire remains a mystery? 
 
 In considering this question, there are important differences 
 to be borne in mind between the French Code and the Egyptian 
 Code. 
 
 Presumption against lessee in French law. 
 
 Under the French Code the lessee of a house has the duty of 
 restoring it at the end of the lease, and is not released from this 
 duty by proving that it was destroyed or damaged by fire. 
 
 He must prove in addition that the fire occurred by fortuitous 
 event or irresistible force, or owing to a fault of construction, or 
 that it was communicated from a neighbouring house. (C. C. F. 
 1733; B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 3rd ed. 1, n. 972; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1733, n. 3.) 
 
 This article creates an exception to the rules of proof and it 
 ought not to be extended by analogy. In particular, the position 
 of the article in the French Code and the terms vice de construc- 
 tion and maison voisine show that it was not meant to apply to 
 the lease of a moveable thing. It is significant that the corre- 
 sponding article in the Civil Code of Quebec is limited to 
 "premises leased" (art. 1629). (Sic. Esmein, Dissertation in 
 note to S. 84. 1. 33; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 5, p. 326, and 
 note 28, 3rd ed. But many writers are of the opposite opinion, 
 B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 1, n. 1004; Guillouard, Louage, 2, n. 
 680: D. N. C. C. art. 1733, n. 18.) 
 
 As applied to the lease of a house, the onus of proof is thrown 
 on the lessee, and the jurisprudence and especially the decisions 
 of the Cour de Cassation apply the rule very strictly. The 
 lessee is not exonerated merely if no specific fault is proved 
 against him, nor by proof that he took all reasonable care, and that 
 there are circumstances which make it likely that the fire was 
 caused by a fortuitous event, such as the fault of a stranger. He 
 must prove the precise manner in which the fire originated if ho 
 
 
 > W 
 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 301 
 
 is to show that he was free from fault. (Req. 25 oct. 1911, 
 D. 1912. 1. 225.; 
 
 Even the proof that the fire originated in a neighbouring 
 building is not conclusive, for it may appear that it would not 
 have arisen at all or would not have spread to the house occupied 
 by the lessee but for fault on his part. (Req. 30 janv. 1804, 
 D. 54. 1. 95; Cass. 27 oct. 1913, D. 1916. 1. 84. S. 1914. 1. 
 332.) 
 
 An example of the rigour with which the rule is applied is 
 afforded by a case in which it was held that the lessee was not 
 liberated by proof that a fire was caused by a short circuit in his 
 electric wiring. (Toulouse, 19 mai 1912, D. 1914. 2. 166. See 
 Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 182.) 
 
 Many of the authors approve of this jurisprudence. (Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 5, p. 318; B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 1, n. 978; 
 D. N. C C. art. 1733, n. 168.) 
 
 On the other hand, other authors contend that the lessee may 
 prove that it was impossible for him to prevent the fire although 
 he fails to prove positively by what means it was caused. And 
 there are many arrets in this sense. (Laurent, 25, n. 279; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 1718; Douai, 28 mars 1901, D. 1901. 2. 233; 
 Lyon, 15 janv. 1907, D. 1908. 2. 207; D. N. C. C. art. 1733, 
 n. 151.) 
 
 No presumption against lessee in Egyptian law. 
 
 It is not necessary for us to decide between the two sysiernes 
 just stated, because in the Egyptian Code there is no article 
 corresponding with C. C. F. 1733. 
 
 In the Egyptian law, therefore, the general rules apply, and 
 the lessor cannot recover from the lessee damages for the loss 
 caused by the fire except by proving that the fire was due to the 
 lessee's fault. (C. A. Alex. 27 fevr. 1879, R. O. IV, 157; 
 C. A. Alex. 29 janv. 1880, R. O. V, 125; C. A. Alex. 27 mai 
 1880, Borelli, art. 463, 4; C. A. Alex. 9 mars 1899, B. L. J. V, 
 157; C. A. Alex. 1 juin 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 289; De Hults, 
 Rep. vo. Louage, n. 119; Grandmoulin, Contrats, n. 393. Contra, 
 C. A. 21 mars 1901, O. B. Ill, n. 23, p. 27.) 
 
 Rule in Egyptian law. 
 
 In the Egyptian law whether the question arises between the 
 lessor and the lessee or between other parties, the court is entitled 
 
302 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 to rely on presumptions. It may well be that the court is 
 satisfied that the defendant has disproved his responsibility for 
 the lire although its precise origin remains obscure. 
 
 The nature of the proof required varies according to circum- 
 stances. When the defendant is a common carrier it is par- 
 ticularly hard for him to prove that the fire which prevented him 
 from performing his contract originated without his fault, seeing 
 that in such a business there are many possibilities of fire being 
 caused by the fault of employees. (Cass. 27 oct. 1913, D. 1916. 
 1. 84: Josserand, Les Transport*, n. 585; B.-L. et Wahl. Louage, 
 3rd ed. 2, n. 3535; Lyon-Caen et Renault, TraiU de Droit Com- 
 mercial, 4th ed. 3, n. 603; Rev. Trim. 1914, p. 131.) 
 
 Sickness or epidemic as force majeure. 
 
 The question whether the illness of the debtor, or some infirmity, 
 bodily or mental, supervening after the date of the contract, which 
 prevents him from performing his obligation is to be considered 
 as force majeure, depends upon the nature of the contract and the 
 implied intention of the parties. 
 
 When the contract is a contract for the hire of personal services 
 the Egyptian Code provides — 
 
 A contract for the hire of personal services is dissolced by 
 the death of the person employed or any accidental circumstance 
 which prevents him from working. (C. C. E. 411/502.) 
 
 The French Code has no words corresponding to " any acci- 
 dental circumstance." (C. C. F. 1795.) But it is a settled rule 
 of the French law that when without his fault the servant or 
 workman becomes physically or morally incapable of doing the 
 work promised the contract comes to an end, and no damages 
 are due on either side. (Dall. Rep. Louage d'Ouvrage, n. 66; 
 Beudant, Vente et Louage, n. 676: B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 3rd 
 ed. 2, n. 2902; D. N. C. C. art. 1780, n. 552. See Cass. 7 juin 
 1905, D. 1908. 1. 74.) 
 
 And when the services to be rendered are strictly personal to 
 the master, his illness or infirmity might render the services use- 
 less. In all these contracts for the hire of personal services it is 
 an implied term that the party bound shall be liberated if he 
 cannot perform his obligation owing to an infirmity for which he 
 is not to blame. So, an actor who is prevented by illness from 
 performing is not liable in damages to the manager of the theatre. 
 (Dall. Rep. Theatre, nos. 195 seq.) 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 303 
 
 In a recent ease a dramatic author had bound himself to deliver 
 to a theatre-manager the completed manuscript of a play by a 
 fixed date subject to a penalty. 
 
 Ho was prevented from so doing by trouble with his teeth so 
 severe as to need a surgical operation which rendered intellectual 
 work impossible for him for some weeks. This was considered 
 to be force majeure. (Paris, 7 janv. 1910, D. 1910. 2. 292.) 
 
 But the illness of the debtor is not force majeure if it was 
 caused by his voluntary act or fault. (See Panel. Franc. Oblig. 
 n. 1783.) 
 
 And when it is a question not of performing personal services 
 but of paying money, the French law is very strict in refusing to 
 consider illness as force majeure. Where an insurance policy 
 provided that the policy should lapse if the premium was not 
 paid before a certain day, and the assured was struck "with apoplexy 
 on the day of payment, it was held that this was not force; majeure 
 which relieved him from the consequences of the non-performance. 
 The assured might have made provision for payment by another 
 on his behalf in the event of his being prevented by illness or 
 other incapacity from making the payment himself. (Req. 15 
 juin 1911, D. 1912. 1. 181. Cf. Cass. 16 mars 1864, D. 64. 
 1. 159.) 
 
 In some cases the fact that an epidemic exists in a locality may 
 be considered as force majeure. So it has been held that a theatre- 
 manager could not claim damages from an actor w r ho refused to 
 perform because there was an epidemic of typhoid fever in the 
 place. (Trib. Seine, 17 avril 1869, D. 69. 5. 221; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1148, nos. 69 seq.) 
 
 (b) Events caused by the act of man. 
 
 The act of a third party which renders it impossible for the 
 debtor to perform his contract is a cas fortuit unless the third 
 party is a person for whose fault the debtor is responsible, or 
 unless the act is one which might have been foreseen and guarded 
 against. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 167; B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 1, n. 455; P. N. C. C. art. 1148, n. 126; Cass. 27 
 avril 1898, D. 98. 1. 421; Renncs, 31 dec. 1896, D. 99. 1. 74.) 
 
 For example, the theft of an article by a third party may 
 liberate a depositary or other person who had charge of the thing 
 from his liability in damages for its non-restitution. So, where 
 a creditor held a diamond necklace in pledge and it was stolen 
 
301 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 by burglars, it was held that he was excused from returning it. 
 (C. A. Alex. 20 mars 1889, B. L. J. I, 83. Cf. Cass. 27 avril 
 1898, D.98. 1.421.) 
 
 Special rule as to paid depositary. 
 
 The theft of an article which is in the hands of a depositary i* 
 not force majeure which discharges him from his liability if the 
 thing was stolen by a person for whom he is responsible. And 
 the presumption is that it was stolen by such a person. The 
 Egyptian codes provide — 
 
 The depositary, who receives remuneration in respect of the 
 transactions which, have occasioned the deposit, as for instance 
 an innkeeper, carrier, etc., is liable for the loss of the thing 
 deposited, unless he proves that such loss was brought about by 
 vis major. (C. C. E. 489/598.; 
 
 The Egyptian article is in more general terms than the cor- 
 responding articles in the French Code under which the pre- 
 sumption of fault exists only against the carrier and the hotel- 
 keeper. (C. C. F. 1782, 1953. See Grandmoulin, Cmtrats, 
 n. 898.) 
 
 The theft from a carrier will not be considered as force majeure, 
 unless he proves that it was committed by a person outside his 
 employment. And a theft from an hotel is not force majeure 
 unless it was committed by burglars or by thieves who got into 
 the hotel without permission. It is probable, at any rate, that 
 the Egyptian legislator intends to maintain the rules of the French 
 law upon these points. Under the French Code, the hotel-keeper 
 is responsible for the loss of the thing if it was stolen by a guest 
 in the hotel. (C. C. F. 1953.) And the probability is that the 
 Egyptian law is the same, though there does not appear to be any; 
 jurisprudence in which this has been determined. (See Grand- 
 moulin, Contrats, n. 902; C. A. Alex. 6 juin 1894, B. L. J. 
 VI, 326; C. A. Alex. 13 mai 1895, B. L. J. VII, 318.) 
 
 By a recent loi in France, the hotel-keeper's responsibility is 
 limited to 1,000 francs pour Its especes monnayees, les Valeurs, 
 les titres, les bijoux et les objets precieux de toute nature non 
 deposes reellement entre les mains des aubergistes ou hoteliers. 
 {Loi du 8 avril 1911, amending C. C. F. 1953.) 
 
 The effect of this law is merely to remove the presumption 
 against the hotel -keeper as regards the excess over 1,000 francs. 
 He remains liable to the full amount if fault on his part or on that 
 
NON-PERFOKMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 305 
 
 of his servant is (proved. (B.-L. etWahl, Societe, 3rd cd. n. 1228; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 2222; Cass. 30 mars 1910, S. 1910. 1. 83.; 
 
 Hotel-keepers as a rule endeavour to exclude or to limit their 
 liability by putting notices in the rooms used by the guests 
 declaring that they will 1 not be liable for the safety of valuable 
 articles unless deposited in the office. Such notices are considered 
 by a part of the French doctrine as a sufficient limitation in 
 circumstances in which it is reasonable to presume that the guest 
 accepted the accommodation on these conditions. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 2223; Dall. Supp'vo. Depot, n. 69; B.-L. et Wahl, Socictr, 
 n. 1234.) 
 
 But the better opinion appears to be that the guest cannot be 
 considered as having assented to such an exclusion or limitation 
 of the hotel-keeper's legal responsibility; L' expression des desirs 
 d'un wantr e d'hotel ne pent equivaloir a un contrat. (Rouen. 
 18 juillet 1889, sous Aix, 26 oct. 1899, D. 1901. 2. 303; Sourdat, 
 Responsabilite, 2, n. 935; Laurent, 27, n. 145; Gombert, Jules. 
 Des Rapports Juridiques entre Hoteliers, Aubergistes et 
 Voyagews, 1900, these, Lille, p. 151. See Rev. Trim. 1914, 
 p. 313.) 
 
 The fact that in France it has been necessary to create a limita- 
 tion of the liability by special laws supports this contention. 
 And it is noteworthy that both the German and the Swiss codes, 
 although they limit the hotel-keeper's liability, unless fault is 
 proved, do not allow him to decline his responsibility by putting 
 up notices of this kind. (German Code, art. 701; Swiss Code 
 Oblig. art. 489.) 
 
 Special liability of hotel-keeper not to be extended by 
 
 analogy. 
 
 In France the article which creates the presumption against 
 the hotel-keeper is limited to him, and is strictly interpreted. 
 
 The special liability of the hotel-keeper for one kind of 
 fortuitous event, that is, for loss caused by thefts committed by 
 a third party, is a traditional rule of the law for which various 
 reasons have been given, but this special liability will not be 
 extended by analogy. (Planiol, 2, n. 2225; D. N. C. C. art. 
 1952, n. 8.) It does not apply to people who do not supply 
 lodging, nor to those whose lodgers are of a permanent kind. So 
 the liability does not extend to a lodging-house keeper, at anv 
 rate when the lodger has taken the room for a considerable time. 
 
 w.— VOL. II. 20 
 
 
 MS l AlAJ tS ■ 
 
 M l 
 
306 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (Cass. 25 juiii 1913, D. 1914. 1. 243. Contra, B.-L. et Wah'l, 
 Societe, n. 1238; D. N, C. C. art. 1952, n. 22, and n. 82.) 
 
 Still less does the liability exist in the case of doctors, dentists, 
 or others in regard to coats and similar articles left by patients in 
 the ante-room . If the doctor or dentist prove that he took ordinary 
 care he is discharged of his responsibility. (C. de Cass, de Rome, 
 13 mai 1913, D. 1914. 2. 65, and note by M. Valery.) But 
 when a want of reasonable care is proved the theft will not be 
 considered as force majeure. (Cass. 6 now 1907, D. 1909. 1. 
 13.) 
 
 But the terms of the Egyptian article are wider than those of 
 the French codes. By the Egyptian law any " paid depositary " 
 must prove force majeure if he is to be liberated. No doubt such 
 persons as cafe-keepers and restaurant-keepers will be included 
 under that head if the article was placed in their care. And 
 this means in the case of theft that such a depositary must prove 
 that the article was stolen by a third party in the sense above 
 explained, that is, not by one of the depositary's servants, and, 
 probably, that this third party was there without leave. 
 
 War, invasion, etc. 
 
 Such events as war, invasion by an enemy, blockadp, attacks of 
 brigands, riots and other disturbances of the public peace, if they 
 entirely prevent the execution of the obligation will be illustrations. 
 of force majeure. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 455; Pand. 
 Franc, vo. Obligations, nos. 1805 seq.: D. N. C. C. art. 1148, 
 nos. 77 seq.) 
 
 The plea that the debtor was prevented by war from fulfilling 
 his obligation will be more fully discussed later. 
 
 Fait du prince. 
 
 The passing of a law or regulation by a constituted authority, 
 or any command or prohibition issued by the public authority to 
 which the debtor is bound by law to submit, may prevent the 
 execution of a contract. When this occurs, it is a cas fortuit. 
 For this kind of fortuitous event the term fait du prince is the 
 consecrated expression in the French law. Acts of very various 
 kinds may present this character. The expropriation of property 
 by the state, or the requisition of supplies by the government, 
 the prohibition of certain industries or of certain exports, the 
 closing of a theatre by tin' public authority, or an order forbidding 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 307 
 
 ;a manager of a theatre from allowing a certain actor to perform 
 are examples of fait du prince. (B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 45-5, 1; 
 Pand. Franc, vo. Obligations, n. 1849 seq.; D. N. C. C. arts. 
 1148, nos. 113 seq.) If in a contract between a tramway-com- 
 pany and the syndicate of tramway workers certain hours of work 
 are agreed upon, and a law is passed under which it is impossible 
 for the workers to fulfil this contract, this is force majeure. (Req. 
 26 juill. 1909, S. 1910. 1. 71.) 
 
 Force majeure must create an impossibility. 
 
 But such events as war, invasion by an enemy, attacks of 
 brigands, riots, and so forth, do not amount to fortuitous event 
 unless they entirely prevent the execution of the contract. If they 
 merely make its execution more difficult they will not be con- 
 sidered as cas fortuit. (See B.-L. et Wahl, Louage, 3rd ed. 2, 
 n. 2900; Cons. d'Etat, 9 dec. 1887, D. 88. 5. 497; Req. 27 oct. 
 1908, D. 1910. 1. 311; C. A. Alex. 20 juin 1906, B. L. J. 
 XVIII. 335.) The defence of war as force majeure may be 
 taken as an example. 
 
 War as force majeure. 
 
 After the outbreak of the European war of 1914 this matter 
 became one of the greatest importance, but the principles 
 applicable to it have^ been long established. (See Schaffhauser, 
 M., Lois Nouvelles, 1915, pp. 25, 41, 65, and 81; La Guerre 
 consideree comme force majeure dans les ventes de Marchandises, 
 by M. A. Wahl, in Rev. Trim. 1915, pp. 355, 383, 518, 519; 
 Rev. Trim. 1914, pp. 442, 776; and in Louage de services, 
 Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 5; M. S. Serbesco, Effets de la Guerre sur 
 ■ V Execution des Contrats, in Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 349; and the 
 rapidly growing jurisprudence indexed in Dalloz and Sirey under 
 Guerre de 1914; note to S. 1916. 1. 17; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, 
 nos. 77 seq.; Josserand, Les Transports, n. 586, and n. 898.) 
 
 War does not of itself suspend the operation of the ordinary 
 rules of law. As the Mixed Court of Appeal expressed it in a 
 recent case: En ce qui concerne les relations entre particuUers, 
 les principes superieurs du droit ri'ont pas ete aneantis par la 
 grande guerre. (C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1916, B. L. J. XXIX, 
 107.) 
 
 Or, in the words of the Court of Paris, il n'est pas possible de 
 -dire en principe, que Vetat de guerre constitue par lui-merme la 
 
 '20 (2) 
 
308 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 force majeure permettant de jaire echec a tous les contrats. (Paris,. 
 8 juill. 1916, D. 1916. 2, 169, 3me espece. Cf. Caen, 24 fevr. 
 1915, D. 1916. 2. 22.) 
 
 But the state of war may be, according to circumstances, force 
 majeure. 
 
 There are two classes of cases more particularly in which the 
 defence is common that the defendant is excused by war, viz.: 
 (1) actions by citizens against the state claiming indemnity for 
 losses caused to them by fait de guerre, a subject which falls 
 under the head of the responsibility of the state, and (2) the case 
 where a party to a contract pleads that he has been prevented 
 by war from executing his contract. 
 
 There are many ways in which war may render the performance 
 of a contract impossible. If, in consequence of the invasion of 
 the enemy, shops or places of business have to be closed, the 
 employer cannot be compelled to pay wages to his employees 
 during the period of necessary closing. In France special laws 
 have been passed as to the effect of war upon leases of houses and 
 leases of farms. (Loi du 9 mars 1918, baux a loyer, and lot du 
 17 aoul 1917, baux ruraux.) With these we are not concerned. 
 The French cases prior to these lois apply the principles of the 
 general law which are followed in Egypt. (Baudry-Lacan- 
 tinerie et Wahl, Louage, 3rd ed. 2, n. 2900; Trib. de 
 la Seine, 20 janv. 1915, S. 1916. 2. 52; Eev. Trim. 1915, p. 519.) 
 If the head of a business is mobilised it may be necessary for him 
 to close his premises at once, and he may be excused from giving 
 notice to his employees. (See Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 520.) So, 
 in the case of the employee. La mobilisation, fait exterieur et 
 independant de la volonte des parties rend impossible a Vouvrier 
 ou employe mobilise V accomplissement de son engagement, et, des 
 lors, constitue un cas de force majeure, tant que cette impossibilite 
 subsiste, mais elle rta pas pour effet la rupture definitive du contrat 
 de travail; elle en entraine seulement la suspension. (Trib. Civ. 
 de la Seine, 2 mars 1915, Trib. Com. de Nancy, 6 dec. 1915, D. 
 1916. 2. 101. If a theatre is closed by a public authority in 
 consequence of a war the lessee will not be bound to pay the rent. 
 (Trib. Seine, lor mai 1915; Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 517; Guillouard, 
 Louage, 1, n. 391.) 
 
 In a recent decision the Tribunal de la Seine goes further. 
 
 A theatre was closed by the public authorities during a certain 
 period, after which it was allowed to open under restrictions. 
 The performances were to be reduced, and so forth. Partly from 
 
 ■^ ******* . . r 
 
 ... 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 309 
 
 these reasons, and partly owing to the darkness of the streets and 
 the difficulties of transit, there was a great falling off in the 
 receipts of the theatre. In these circumstances, the court held 
 that the lessee was entitled not only to escape payment of rent 
 during the time that the theatre was closed but also to a reduction 
 for the subsequent period. (Trib. Seine, ut sup.) 
 
 If a city is bombarded and the inhabitants have to leave their 
 houses, they will not have to pay rent for them during this com- 
 pulsory absence. (Trib. de paix de Paris, 27 janv. 1871, D. 71. 
 3. 6. Cf. Paris, 28 aout 1873, D. 74. 2. 159; Trib. cle la Seine, 
 20 janv. 1915, S. 1916. 2. 52; Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 355, 1917, 
 p. 153.) 
 
 An order for the mobilisation and the requisitioning of all the 
 means of transport may relieve a railway-company of many of 
 its obligations to private shippers of goods. (See Montpellier, 
 15 juill. 1915, and the group of cases in D. 1916. 2. 49.) 
 
 In a recent Egyptian case of great importance, the defendant 
 had broken several contracts between himself and the plaintiff. 
 The defence was that it was impossible for him to perform the 
 contracts, because he was an enemy subject, and his business had 
 been put into the hands of a liquidator in conformity with the 
 proclamation of the military authority in Egypt. The Mixed 
 Tribunal of Alexandria rejected this defence and sustained the 
 liability of the defendant. 
 
 The grounds of this decision were that the measures prescribed 
 by the proclamations against enemy subjects were intended to 
 cause prejudice to these enemies and not to give them a defence 
 against actions, and that the orders to liquidate could' not be 
 considered as force majeure, because the military authority avail 
 erige en faute le fait seul d 'appartenir a une nation ennemic. 
 
 But this judgment was reversed upon appeal and the law was 
 thus laid down: 
 
 En ce qui conoerne les relations entre particuliers, les principes 
 superieurs du droit n'ont pas ete aneantis par les evenements de la 
 grande guerre. 
 
 Lorsque les sujets des pays ennemis se defendant devant eux, 
 les tribunaux dowent lew faire V application des dispositions des 
 codes, mais aussi l&Ur en conserver le benefice; par suite le res* 
 sortissant ennemi nest tenu de dommages-interets pour inexecu- 
 tion d'un contrat que s'il a commis une faute. 
 
 On ne peut retenir commie une faute a sa charge le seul fait 
 ■quil appurtient a une nation ennemie. 
 
310 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Les actes de Vauforite militaire, tels qn'un ordre de liquider 
 une maison de commerce, dont un sujet ennemi est le premier a 
 soaffrir, peuvent etre im'oques par lui oomme un cos de force 
 majeure. (C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1916, 13. L. J. XXIX, 107.) 
 
 Tho Mixed Court of Appeal pointed out that the compulsory 
 liquidation of the business of enemy traders was intended to deal 
 a blow at the general trade of the enemy country, but did not. 
 aim at inflicting a direct injury on individual traders. 
 
 It is in questions of sale, however, that the defence of war as 
 force majeure has been most frequently raised. It is settled by 
 the jurisprudence that war does not release the debtor from his- 
 liability in damages for his .non-performance, although the war 
 has rendered this performance more difficult and more expensive. 
 (Cass. 19 nov. 1873, D. 74. 1. 200; Trib. Comm. Seine, 9 mars, 
 et 15 juin 1915, D. 1916. 2. 22; Civ. 4 aout 1915, D. 1916. 1. 
 22, S. 1916. 1. 17; cases in Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 384; C. A. 
 Alex. 29 mai 1912, B.L.J. XXIV, 368.) 
 
 In an Egyptian case a merchant in Genoa had sold goods to be- 
 transported by sea to Alexandria. He excused his non-perform- 
 ance by alleging the outbreak of the Italian-Turkish war. It 
 was held that this was not force majeure . 
 
 The war made the performance of the contract more difficult,, 
 but it did not make it impossible. (C. A. Alex. 29 mai 1912, 
 ut supra.) The same principle was applied when a partner 
 pleaded that he could not execute his obligation to make his apport, 
 because, owing to the war, he could not realise certain securities- 
 which he had. This was held not to be an absolute impossibility. 
 (Q. A. Alex. 17 janv. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 157.) 
 
 In France where game-shooting was prohibited during the war,, 
 game multiplied upon lands belonging to the state and caused 
 damage to neighbouring owners. In an action against the state 
 for damage caused in this way by game increasing on domain, 
 lands, the state pleaded, (1) that the shooting was let to a lessee,. 
 and (2) that the interdiction of shooting was force majeure which 
 prevented them from keeping down the head of game. The court 
 repelled both defences. As owner the state was bound to prevent 
 the excessive multiplication of game, and there was no force- 
 majeure, because it was not proved that they could not have 
 obtained authorisation to destroy the game without the use of 
 guns. (Trib. de Rambouillet, 23 mai 1916, Rev. Trim. 1917,. 
 p. 130.) 
 
 Nor can the debtor excuse himself by pleading war if, in spite 
 
NON- PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 311 
 
 of the war, he could have performed his contract before the war 
 began. (Trib. Conmi. Seine, 2 janv. 1871, D. 71. 3. 17. See 
 Wahl, A., in Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 7 for illustrations. 
 
 Ami, as a general rule, the war does not put an end to the con- 
 tract, but only delays its performance. (See Rev. Trim. 1917, 
 p. 153.) So in the case of a lease of shooting rights, if, during 
 the war, shooting game is prohibited this suspends the lease. Rent 
 is not due during this period. (Paris, 16 oct. 1916, Rev. Trim. 
 1917, p. 153.") But whether the contract is merely suspended 
 or altogether terminated is largely a matter of circumstances and 
 of interpretation. In many cases of sale, for example, the courts 
 will hold that, according to the intention of the parties, the 
 delivery was to be made within a certain delay or not at all, and 
 they will not compel the buyer to take delivery if it is offered 
 after this delay, though the seller may be without fault. (Req. 
 7 mai 1872, D. 72. 1. 456; and cases in Rev. Trim. 1915, 
 p. 412.) 
 
 If a manufacturer has sold goods of his own manufacture, and 
 his factory is destroyed by the enemy, this will be force majeure. 
 But if his contract was to supply goods of a certain kind, but not 
 necessarily made by him, it will be his duty to get them elsewhere. 
 And it is no excuse for non-performance that a seller was reckon- 
 ing on getting the goods from a particular manufacturer, and that 
 this manufacturer, in consequence of the war, is unable to supply 
 them. (C. A. Alex. 7 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 416. ) 
 
 The seller will be excused if, after the sale, the exportation of 
 goods of that kind is prohibited. (Req. 15 nov. 1894, S. 96. 1. 
 142.) 
 
 The seller of goods may be excused by the fact that all goods 
 of the kind sold by him have been requisitioned by the military 
 authority, whether of his own state, or of an invading enemy. 
 (Req. 21 fevr. 1876, S. 77. 1. 157, D. 77. 1. 367.) 
 
 Or an enemy army may have compelled the seller to deliver 
 to them or to a third party the goods promised to the buyer. 
 (Req. 29 oct. 1908, D. 1910. 1. 311.) 
 
 In a case in Egypt the sale was of Welsh coal. The seller 
 pleaded that the exportation of this coal from Great Britain had 
 been prohibited, and that the military authorities in Egypt had 
 requisitioned all coal of that kind in the depots at Alexandria. 
 The Mixed Court of Appeal held that the plea of force majeure 
 was in these circumstances made out; il zacfit (Tun jail (hi prince 
 tres caracterise. (C. A. Alex. 10 mai 1910, B. L. J. XXVIII. 
 
312 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 306. Cf. C. A. Alex. 11 avr. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 358;, 
 C. A. Alex. 2 mai 1917, B. L. .7. XXIX, 396.) In the case of 
 11 avril 1917, it was not necessary to decide this question because 
 the court held that the buyer had acquiesced in the request of the 
 seller to treat the contract as being resiliated. 
 
 The same reasons which justify non -performance will justify 
 delay in the performance; so, for example, a seller may be excused 
 for non-performance at the time promised, by proving that his 
 delay was caused by the railways being taken up with troop-trains. 
 (Trib. Comm. de Perpignan, 5 fevr. 1915, Rev. Trim. 1915, 
 p. 405.) 
 
 In spite of the weight of authority that war is not to be con- 
 sidered as force majeure when it merely renders the performance 
 of a contract more difficult or more onerous, some French courts 
 have been bold enough to break away from the tradition. Thus, 
 in one case it was held:— 
 
 Si les engagements contraries doivent etre executes conforme- 
 ment aux termes de la convention, il faut necessairement que cette 
 execution puisse soperer dans les circonstances courantes et in- 
 herentes a la vie economique normale, telle qiielle se deroulait 
 au moment des accords. 
 
 Par suite, Vetat de guerre actuel, ay ant trouble profondement 
 la vie economique du pays, et cree dans la commerce et V Industrie 
 des situations critiques et difficiles, qui ne permettent pas d'obligeY 
 ceux qui en sont victimes a remplir des engagements ruineux, 
 cette situation doit suspendre les engagements dans certaineS 
 branches commerciales ou faire nuitre entre les parties de nouveaux 
 accords a litre temporaire. 
 
 Specialement, doit etre deboute de sa demande en paiement, 
 pendant la guerre, des appointements quit touchait auparavant, 
 en vertu de son contrat avec son patron, le coupeur, employe chez 
 un mawhand-tailleur de luxe, s'adressant a une clientele speciale 
 que Vetat de guerre a dispersee et fait disparaitre en grande partie, 
 en paralysanl avnsi V exercice de m profession et en rrndamt muffles 
 les concours dont il setait entoure. 
 
 But the decision appears to be contrary to principle, and it is 
 unfavourably criticised by the arretiste. (Trib. Comm. de Tou- 
 louse, ler juin 1915, S. 1916. 2. 29. See note to C. A. Alex. 
 7 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 416.) 
 
 And in another case, the court, without going so far as this, 
 reduced the damages on account of the difficulty of executing the 
 contract. The case was by a lessee of a flat against the lessor 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 313 
 
 who had bound himself to heat the apartment Let, and failed to 
 do so owing to the difficulty of procuring coal and to its high 
 price, these being effects of the war. v Trib. de la Seine, 30 nov. 
 1916, S. 1916, 2. 40. See Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 104.; Such 
 a decision is contrary to all traditional rules on the matter. 
 
 It has been decided that when the effect of the war is to dimmish 
 the profits of the lessee without depriving him of the possession 
 of the subject leased, this does not entitle him to a reduction of 
 his rent. (Cass. 21 janv. 1874, S. 1874. 1. 125, Journal du 
 Palais, 74, p. 288; Trib. de Cusset, 22 janv. 1915, S. 1916. 2. 53, 
 guests leaving hotel on account of outbreak of war, Trib. de la 
 Seine, 6 dec. 1915, D. 1916. 2. 83.) 
 
 Criticism of the jurisprudence and proposals to change 
 
 the law. 
 
 The law with regard to Avar as force majeure cannot be con- 
 sidered as equitable. It is not in practice possible for the parties 
 to commercial contracts to estimate beforehand the probabilities 
 of an outbreak of war. 
 
 War, as it is now carried on, interferes in the most violent 
 way even with neutral commerce. The effect of holding that the 
 party must execute his contract, even though it has become more 
 difficult and more expensive owing to the war, may be that this 
 party is ruined, while the other party finds himself unjustly en- 
 riched by obtaining at a low price products which have risen 
 enormously in value. 
 
 A. recent writer contends ingeniously that without a change in 
 the existing texts of the law the courts are entitled to grant the 
 dissolution of a contract although its performance has not been 
 rendered impossible. 
 
 He argues that this may be done when a supervening event has 
 rendered the performance more difficult or more onerous, provided 
 that this event combines the following conditions: — 
 
 (1) It must be an event which the parties could not have fore- 
 seen ; 
 
 (2) It must have been entirely independent of the will of the 
 debtor; and 
 
 • (3) It must create such a difficulty in the performance that the 
 party would not have contracted if he had foreseen it. 
 
 It is maintained that it is an implied term of any contract that 
 the debtor is to be freed by the happening of 'an event of this kind. 
 (Serbesco, M. S., in Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 349.) 
 
314 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 So far this argument has not prevailed in the French courts. 
 But in certain classes of cases the English courts, as will be shown 
 later, have managed to arrive at pretty much the same result 
 as that for which M. Serbesco contends. (Infra, p. 321.) 
 
 In Italy the decret of 27 mai 1915, n. 739, has remedied this 
 inequity by enacting la guerre est consideree comme force majeure, 
 non settlement, lorsqu'elle rend impossible Vexecution, nun's aussi 
 lorsqu'elle rend Vexecution excessivement onereuse. (See article 
 by M. E. Piola Caselli, La Legislation de Guerre en Italic in 
 L'Egypte Contemporaine, 1917, p. 241.) 
 
 In France the association of manufacturers and merchants 
 petitioned the Government to pass a law in the same sense. A 
 pro jet de loi of a more general kind was introduced in the French 
 Chamber by M. Faillot on 12 August, 1915. (Journ. Off. Doc. 
 Pari. Chambre, p. 934.) 
 
 The proposition was that commercial contracts concluded before 
 1st October, 1914, for the delivery of products or merchandise or 
 for other successive or deferred prestations might be revised, sus- 
 pended, or resiliated, with or without indemnity, if the conditions 
 of execution, in consequence of the war, had undergone changes 
 which the parties could not have contemplated, and such, that if the 
 debtor had foreseen them, he would not have bound himself or 
 would have bound himself only upon different terms. 
 
 Such questions were to be decided by a court of arbitration, 
 composed of a judge and of two assessors; the procedure was to be 
 in writing and there was to be no appeal. 
 
 The law was to cease to have effect six months after the sign- 
 ing of peace. (Rev. Trim. 1915, p. 720, 1917, p. 258.) 
 
 But this law was not carried. Special laws were passed in 
 France in the latter part of the war as to the effect of war upon 
 baux a loger and baux ruraux. (Loi du 9 mars 1918, and Loi du 
 17 aout 1917.) 
 
 Strikes. 
 
 Whether a strike amounts to force majeure excusing the exe- 
 cution of the contract is a question of circumstances. If the strike 
 is general, including all the works of a certain kind, it may make 
 it impossible for the debtor to fulfil his obligation . But in other 
 cases the difficulty may be got over by going elsewhere. If the 
 contract was to deliver a product which is made only by one 
 maker, a strike in his works might be cas fortuity excusing a 
 merchant who had undertaken to supply goods of this manufac- 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEB LOR. 315 
 
 turer. But if the strike occurs in the works of the debtor himself 
 it is not a cas fortuit if it was brought about by his own fault, or 
 if it rests with him to bring- it to an end. II y a lieu dans chaque 
 espece de rechereher si la greve a eu pour origin? une faute grave 
 del' entrepreneur, si elle pouvait etre evitec ou arretee par lui, et 
 si elle a constitue pour ltd un obstacle insurmon table a I 'execution 
 de ses obligations. (Conseil d'Etaf, 3 juill. 1912, D. 191G. 3. 3, 
 lere espece; Req. 22 avr. 1909, D. 1913. 1. 136; Req. 28 oct. 
 1907, D. 1909. 1. 282; note by M. A. Colin to Paris, 13 nov. 
 1903, D. 1904. 2. 73; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, nos. 204 seq., and 
 Additions, 1913, art. 1148, nos. 204 seq. ; C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 
 1899, B. L. J. XII, 39. See Rev. Trim. 1908, p. 613. As 
 to the question whether the workman who strikes commits a breach 
 of the contract which entitles his employer to resiliate the contract 
 of service, see Cass. 18 mars 1902, S. 1903. 1. 465; and Sirey, 
 Table, 1901—1910, vo. Louage de services, n. 105.) 
 
 Onus of proof of fortuitous event. 
 
 The debtor who pleads thai the reason why he has not executed 
 his contract is because W was prevented by a fortuitous event has 
 the burden of proof. He must prove the evemt and he must 
 prove also that it occurred without his fault. In some cases the 
 mere proof of the event will exclude the idea of fault. As a 
 general rule a debtor who proves that the inexecution was due to 
 such events as earthquakes, lightning, or floods, does not need to 
 prove positively that he could not prevent these occurrences. If 
 the creditor maintains that, notwithstanding the fortuitous event, 
 there was fault on the part of the debtor, it is for him to prove it. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 466; Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 169, note 36.) But there are other events such as fire, or theft 
 committed by a third party, which may have prevented the exe- 
 cution of the obligation, and yet are not necessarily fortuitous so 
 as to excuse the debtor from performance. The fire may have 
 been caused by the fault of the debtor, or the thing may have 
 been stolen by some person for whom he is responsible, or it may 
 have been stolen owing to his negligence. 
 
 In these cases the debtor must prove not only that the event 
 happened and caused the inexecution, but also that it happened 
 without his fault. (See, as to theft, Cass. 8 nov. 1881, S. 83. 1. 
 167.) The exact nature of the proof which he must make in the 
 case of fire has been discussed earlier. (Supra, pp. 299 seq.) 
 
 '''fa 7WK^ 
 
316 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Effect of fortuitous event. 
 
 When the fortuitous event which the debtor proves in excuse 
 for the non-execution is of a kind merely to cause delay, and not to 
 prevent the execution altogether, the debtor will be excused only 
 for the damages caused by the delay, and will be bound to execute 
 his obligation when the obstacle is removed. (Cass. 15 fevr. 1888, 
 D. 88. 1. 208; Trib, Civ. de la Seine, 2 mars et 21 avril 1915, 
 Trib. Com. de Nancy, 6 dec. 1915, D. 1916. 2. 101.) 
 
 But when the effect of the fortuitous event is to make the per- 
 formance of the obligation altogether impossible the obligation is 
 rescinded, and the parties are put back as far as possible into their 
 former position. Tf any payment has been made or anything 
 delivered it must be returned by the debtor who owing to the for- 
 tuitous event cannot fulfil his part of the obligation. But the 
 debtor is not excused by proof of a fortuitous event if the impossi- 
 bility arose after he was in default, or if he had especially under- 
 taken to be responsible for fortuitous events. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 1, n. 461; Planiol, 2, n. 233; D. N. C. C. art. 1148, 
 nos. 32 seq.) 
 
 The rules on this subject are clearly stated in the Egyptian 
 Code: Obligations are extinguished by dissolution, when, after 
 they have come into existence, performance of them has become 
 impossible. 
 
 If performance has become impossible through the fault of the 
 debtor, or if the impossibility has ((risen while the debtor is in 
 default as regards execution, he is liable for damages. 
 
 When an obligation is dissolved in, consequence of impossibility 
 of performance, the correlative obligations are in like manner 
 dissolved, without prejudice to the right to indemnity, if cmy, due 
 from, the respective parties for any benefit acquired without cause. 
 (Arts. 177—179/240—242.) This means that there must be a 
 restitutio in integrum. The debtor' who cannot make the per- 
 formance which he has promised is excused, but he cannot retain 
 what, has been paid to him. (Dall. Rep. Obligations, n. 740; 
 Req. 14 mai 1872, D. 73. 1. 78.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code in saying the correlative obligations are 
 i)i like manner dissolved clears up a difficulty which arises under 
 the corresponding article of the French Code (art. 1302). That 
 article says that when a corps certain which a debtor was bound to 
 deliver perishes without his fault — Vobiigation est eteinte. 
 
 It does not say that the corresponding obligations of the creditor 
 
 tL J'toiAy fid M**> 
 
NON-PERFOKMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. '517 
 
 are likewise extinguished. The French article is concerned only 
 with the obligation to deliver a specific thing and not with the 
 obligation to do or not to do. In regard to the obligation to do or 
 not to do, the French authors agree that if the debtor is prevented 
 by a fortuitous event from the fulfilment of his obligation the 
 obligation of the creditor is likewise extinguished. This rests 
 upon the theory that in the synallagmatic contracts the two obliga- 
 tions are reciprocal; each of them is the cause of the other, and the 
 extinction of one entails the extinction of the' other. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 621: B.-L. et Barde, Obliy. 1, n. 445: Laurent, 18, n. -509; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 406.) 
 
 Article 1302 of the French Code lays down a different rule for 
 the obligation to deliver a specific thing. In this case, the debtor 
 alone is excused by the fortuitous event which makes it impos- 
 sible for him to deliver the thing, but this event does not affect 
 the correlative obligation of the creditor. This is because the 
 French Code in another place, when dealing with the obligation to 
 deliver a specific thing, says that the thing is to be at the risk of the 
 creditor from the date of the contract (art. 1138). But the 
 Egyptian Code has no corresponding article, and, in spite of the 
 difficulty of reconciling the articles in the Egyptian Code upon 
 risk in the contract of sale, it would appear that the Egyptian 
 legislator intends to lay down a universal rule. The fortuitous 
 event which relieves the debtor puts an end to the obligations on 
 both sides, and there must be a restitutio in integrum. In the 
 case of sale if the buyer has paid the price he can get it back again. 
 (C. C. E. 266/336, 297/371 . Contrast, in France, Pothier, Vmte, 
 n. 307; Guillouard, Vente, 1, n. 264.) This point will be more 
 fully explained later in discussing the extinction of an obligation 
 by the loss of the thing due. (Infra, p. 476.) 
 
 Fortuitous event in contract of lease. 
 
 In the contract of lease of a thing the code lays down special 
 rules as to the effect of a fortuitous event upon the rights of the 
 lessor and the lessee. 
 
 The fortuitous event may have altogether destroyed the thing 
 let, and in that case the contract is dissolved for the future, but the 
 rent paid for the period before the fortuitous event does not need 
 to be returned because the lessee has had the use of the subject. 
 (C. C. E. 370/454, 455; C. C. F. 1722. See Pans, 1 avril 
 1886, D. 68. 2. 85; B.-L. et Wahl, Lottaye, 3rd ed. 1, n. 352.) 
 
 ■ 
 
 
 |fAA«v -W^tvw 
 
318 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But ii* the fortuitous event lias nor destroyed the subject alto- 
 gether, but has deprived the lessee merely of a part of the thing, 
 the lessee has the option, according; to circumstances, of demand- 
 ing either the dissolution of the lease or a reduction in the rent. 
 Ho cannot oblige the lessor to restore the subject to its former 
 state. (Req. 12 janv. 1910, I). 1911. 1. 375.) The full dis- 
 cussion of this matter belongs to the law of lease. 
 
 Right to rebut defence of force majeure may be lost 
 by acquiescence in non-performance. 
 
 Acquiescence in non-performance. 
 
 Before the execution of the contract an event such as the out- 
 break of war may occur which renders its execution impossible, or, 
 at any rate, very difficult. If, in such a case, the debtor intimates 
 to the creditor that he cannot execute the contract and the creditor 
 makes no reply, the court may infer that he acquiesced in the 
 resiliation of the contract, and it may be unnecessary to decide if 
 there was force majeure, because the creditor by his conduct has 
 lost the right to insist on the performance of the contract by the 
 debtor. (C. A. Alex. 11 avril 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 358.) 
 
 Comparison with other laws. 
 Swiss Code. 
 
 The SAviss Code in its general article on the liability of the 
 debtor for inexecution avoids using the terms cas fortuit or force 
 majeure. It says, Lorsque le orecmcier ne peut obtenir V execution 
 de V obligation, on ne peut Vobtenir qu'imparfaitememt, le debiteur 
 est tenu de r Sparer le dommage en resultant, a m'mns qu'il ne 
 prouve qiCaucune faute ne lui est Imputable. (Code des Obliga- 
 tions, art. 97.) 
 
 But in other articles the Swiss Code of Obligations speaks of 
 oas fortuit or force majeure indifferently . (Cf . arts. 103, 299, 306, 
 420, 447, 474, 487, 490. See Rossel et Mentha, Droit Civil 
 Suisse, 3, pp. 128, 154,) 
 
 German Code. 
 
 The corresponding article in the German Code is thus ex- 
 pressed: — Le debiteur se trouve liber e de Vobligation. d'effectuer 
 la prestation, des que celle-ci devient impossible par suite d'une 
 
 ■ 
 
 . 
 
 *f 
 
NON-PKRFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 319 
 
 circohstance survenue depuis la naissance du rapport d'obiiga- 
 tion el dont le debitew n'ait pus a repondre. 
 
 Est assimilee a um im/possibilite survenue depuis la naisscmce 
 du rapport d' obligation Vim/puissance du debiteur, ulterieurement 
 survenue, d'executer la prestation (art. 275). 
 
 In other articles the German Code uses the term force majeure 
 —hohere Gewalt. (See arts. 203, 212, 215, 701, 1996.) 
 
 According- to Cosack, the German Code intends to make the 
 distinction referred to above between accidents arising- out of the 
 enterprise, and accidents which are external to it -innerer Zufall 
 and aiiszerer Zufall. (Lehrbuch des Deutschen biirgerlichen 
 Rechts, 6th ed. 1, pp. 291, 317.) 
 
 The illustration he gives is the special liability of the hotel- 
 keeper, who, under the German Code, is liable for the loss of 
 goods belonging to his guests, unless the damage is caused 
 by the nature of the goods themselves or by forot) mwj&wm 
 (art. 701). In his view, the reason why the hotel-keeper must 
 pay for goods stolen by third parties who are neither his guests 
 nor his servants is because this is a risk which belongs to the 
 enterprise. Other German authorities, however, deny that the 
 criterion of force majeure is that it must be something external. 
 (See note in French translation upon art. 203.) 
 
 In the German law, as in the French, when the impossibility of 
 performance is caused by an event which happens after the date of 
 the contract it is immaterial whether the impossibility is objective 
 or subjective; the only relevant question is whether the debtor is 
 free from fault. (Windscheid, Pandekten, 8th ed. 2, s. 264, n. 2.) 
 
 In regard to the contract of carriage it is a significant fact that 
 the German law does not make the carrier's liability turn on 
 whether the accident was caused by a risk foreign to the enterprise. 
 
 Le voiturier est responsible du dommage resultant de la perte 
 ou de Vavarie survenue, depuis la remise jusqu'a la deliwance de 
 la merchandise, ou du retard dans la delivrance, a moins que la 
 perte, Vavarie ou le retard ne proviennent de circonstances que 
 naurait pu eviter la diligence d'un voiturier prudent. (Code de 
 Commerce Allemand, art. 429.) 
 
 In the German law ordinary carriers can modify the legal rules 
 as to their liability by special contracts, but the power of railways 
 to do so is restricted in various ways. (Code de Comm. Allemand, 
 art. 471.) 
 
320 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 English law as to impossibility of performance. 
 
 Tn the English law when the performance of an agreement has 
 become impossible after its elate owing to a change in the law the 
 agreement is void. (Baily v. De Crespigny, 1869, L. R. 4 Q. B. 
 180, 38 L. J. Q. B. 98; Leiston Gas Co. v. Leiston-cum-Sizewell 
 V. D. C, 1916, 2 K. B. 428, 85 L. J. K. B. 1759.) 
 
 So, for example, the outbreak of war which makes traffic with 
 the enemy country illegal will excuse the non -performance of 
 contracts which involve such prohibited trading. (Arnhold Kar- 
 bcrcj d': Co. v. Blythe, Green, Jourdain & Co., 1916, 1 K. B. 495, 
 85 L. J. K. B. 665. See Barker v. Hodgson, 1814, 3 M. & S. 
 267, 15 R. R. 485; Clapham Steamship Co. v. Nawnlooze Ven- 
 noolschap Vulcacm, 1917, 2 K. B. 639, 86 L. J. K. B. 1439; 
 Baty and Morgan, War, Its Conduct and Legal Results, p. 422;. 
 Page, A., War and Alien Enemies, 2nd ed.; Campbell, H., The 
 Law of War and Contract, p. 64; Mackinnon, F. D., Effect of 
 War on Contract; McNair, A. D., War-Time Impossibility of 
 Performance of Contract, 35 Law Quarterly Review, 84; and 
 supra, I, pp. 123 seq.) When the supervening impossi- 
 bility is not one of law, but of fact, it does not excuse the 
 non-performance of the contract if the contract was an absolute 
 one. The English law does not admit as a general principle that 
 force majeure excuses the non-performance of a contract. So, 
 when a man agreed to deliver a cargo on board in the usual time, 
 and this became impossible owing to the freezing of the canal by 
 which the cargo would have been brought to the ship, it was held 
 he was not excused. (Kearm v. Pearson, 1861, 7 H. & N. 386, 
 31 L.J. Ex. 1,126R.R. 473.) 
 
 A nd if a foreign law prevents the performance the impossibility 
 is one of fact which does not excuse the failure. (Barker v. 
 Hodgson, id supra.) 
 
 The severity of the English law in not admitting force majeure 
 as a defence is, however, greatly mitigated by the fact that the 
 courts treat the question as one of interpretation. In many cases 
 it is held to be an implied term of the contract that the party was 
 to be discharged if the performance became impossible without 
 
 his fault. 
 
 This is so when the parties con tract on the basis of the continued 
 existence of a specific person or thing. The leading case is Taylor 
 
 v. Caldioell. 
 
 " Where from the nature of the contract it appears that the 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 321 
 
 parties must from the beginning have known that it could not be 
 fulfilled unless, whjen the time for the fulfilment of the contract. 
 arrived, some particular specified thing continued to exist, so that 
 when entering into the contract they must, have contemplated such 
 continued existence as the foundation of what was to be done." 
 {Taylor v. Caldwell, 1863, 3 B. & S. 826, 32 L. J. Q. B. 164 T , 
 129 R. R. 573, where see note of the cases in which this principle 
 has been applied.) 
 
 In Taylor v. Caldwell the agreement was to let a music-hall 
 for four days, and before the first of those days arrived the music- 
 hall was burnt down. It was held that both parties were excused. 
 
 In Appleby v. Myers the plaintiffs had contracted to erect 
 certain machinery in the premises of the defendant and to pay a 
 specified sum for the whole work after completion. When the 
 machinery was only partly erected a fire accidentally broke out 
 in the premises, and, without fault by either party, destroyed both 
 the buildings and the machinery then erected thereon. It w r as 
 held that the plaintiffs were not entitled to recover anything for 
 the work done, and that both parties were excused from further 
 performance of the contract. (1867, L. R. 2 C. P. 651, 36 
 L. J. O. P. 331.) 
 
 Upon the same principle, when under a contract an agent was 
 entitled to a salary as a remuneration for his services in intro- 
 ducing clients to a stock-broker, and, owing to the war, the stock- 
 exchange was closed for several months, it was held that no re- 
 muneration could be claimed for this period. It was an implied 
 condition of the contract that the stock-exchange should remain 
 open. {Berthoud v. Schweder & Co., 1915, 31 Times Law Re- 
 ports, 404; Mews' Digest, 1911—1915, p. 1578. See Campbell, 
 H., Law of War and Contract, p. 169.) 
 
 Extension of this principle. 
 
 In recent cases the principle of Taylor v. Caldwell has been 
 extended. The new rule is thus stated by an eminent, judge: — 
 
 " When a lawful contract has been made, and there is no de- 
 fault, a court of law has no power to discharge either party from 
 the performance of it unless either the rights of someone else or 
 some Act of Parliament give the necessary jurisdiction. But a 
 court can and ought to examine the contract and the circumstances 
 in which it was made, not of course to vary, but only to explain it, 
 in order to see whether or not from the nature of it the parties 
 
 AV.— VOL. II. 21 
 
322 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 must have made their bargain on the footing that a particular* 
 thing or state of things would continue to exist; and if they must 
 have done so. then a term to that effect will be implied, although 
 it be not expressed in the contract. In applying this rule it is 
 manifest that such a term can rarely be implied, except where the 
 discontinuance is such as to upset altogether the purpose of the 
 conl ract . Some delay or some change is very common in all human 
 affairs, and it cannot be supposed that any bargain has been made 
 on the tacit condition that such a thing will not happen in any 
 degree." {Per Lord Loreburn, in F. A. Tamplin S. S. Co. v. 
 Anglo- Mexican Petroleum Co., 1916, 2 A. C. 397, 85 L. J. 
 K. B. 1389,1394.) 
 
 Applying this principle, it was held in the following case that 
 a contract of service was terminated. A British ship was in the 
 port of Hamburg at the outbreak of war and was detained there 
 by the German authorities, and the crew were interned for an 
 indefinite time as prisoners. The plaintiff was the wife of one of 
 the officers of the ship. 
 
 Her husband's contract with the shipowner was to serve on the 
 ship on a voyage not exceeding two years' duration. 
 
 He had stipulated that the shipowner should pay part of his 
 wages to his wife. She claimed in this action payment of the 
 proportion of wages earned by her husband after he had been 
 interned as a prisoner. It was held that the shipowner was not 
 liable to pay wages after the date when the crew were interned. 
 [Horlock v. Bed, 1916, 1 A. C. 486, 85 L. J. K. B. 602.) 
 
 The voyage contemplated in the contract had been brought to 
 an end without fault on the part of the defendant, and there was 
 '"the failure of something which was at the basis of the contract 
 in the mind and intention of the contracting parties." 
 
 Instead of the destruction of a specific thing, there is " the 
 cessation or non-existence of an express condition or state of things 
 going to the root of the contract." Per Lord Shaw, 85 L. J. 
 K. B. 618.) But even when the parties have contemplated the 
 possibility of the termination of the contract without liability; 
 owing to the operation of certain causes, such as " restraint of 
 princes," this excuse does not avail unless the foundation of the 
 commercial enterprise contemplated by the parties has been 
 destroyed. If a ship has been chartered for five years and it is 
 requisitioned by the Government for use in war, this does not 
 terminate or even suspend the charter-party if it is still possible 
 that the ship may be released so as to be available for use by the 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 323 
 
 charterers for some months before the expiration of the five pears. 
 F. A. TampMn S. 8. Co. v. Angh-Meociocm Petroleum Pro- 
 tects Co., 1916, 2 A. C. 397, 85 L. J. K. B. 1389. 
 A recent writer states the result of the cases in these terms: 
 llic conclusion seems to be this: If, subsequently to the forma- 
 tion of a contract, an event of which the effects have not been 
 expressly provided for by the terms of the contract occurs, and 
 causes, or is reasonably likely to cause, such difficulty or delay in 
 performance as amounts to commercial impossibility, or destroys 
 the whole foundation of the contract, either [tarty may claim that 
 it was an implied term of the contract that on the happening of 
 th,' said event the obligations of the contract should be discharged. 
 And the court will assent to such claim if it holds, first, that as a 
 matter of construction the alleged implied term was a term of the 
 contract, and. secondly, that the event is of the nature above 
 stated." Mackinnon, F. D., Effect of War on Contract, p. 23. 
 Cf. article by A. D. McNair in 30 Law Quarterly Review, 84, 
 and, especially, at p. 9! I. 
 
 English law as to supervening incapacity to render personal 
 
 services. 
 
 A contract to render personal services, such as can be performed 
 by the debtor only, is subject to the implied condition that he 
 shall be alive and in a state of health to perform the services. If 
 without his fault the debtor should die, or if he should be disabled 
 from performance by illness, the non-performance of the contract 
 is excused. So where a musician contracted to play at a concert, 
 and, owing to illness, she was unable to fulfil her engagement it 
 was held that the illness was a valid excuse. 
 
 It is, probably, an implied term of such a contract that, if tho 
 person disabled by illness has an opportunity of so doing, he 
 shall give to the other party to the contract notice of the disability 
 within a reasonable time. {Robinson v. Davison, 1871, L. R. 
 6 Exoh. 269, 40 L. J. Ex. 172.) 
 
 Impossibility of performance does not cause the contract to 
 be rescinded ab initio. 
 
 According to the English law, the supervening impossibility 
 of performance may, upon the principles above explained, put an 
 end to the contract and release both parties from, further per- 
 formance. But there is not, as in the French law, any restitution 
 
 21 (2) 
 
324 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 in integrum. The contract is valid up to the date when the 
 impossibility arose. If anything has been paid under the contract 
 it cannot be recovered, and if a legal right to claim a payment 
 has accrued before the date of the impossibility, this payment 
 may be claimed in spite of the impossibility. 
 
 The plaintiff agreed to let to the defendant a room for the 
 purpose of seeing the procession which was to have taken place 
 on the occasion of the King's Coronation. The procession had to 
 be postponed owing to the King's illness. The price for the use 
 of the room was, under the contract, payable before the date 
 fixed for the procession, and part of the price had been paid before 
 that date. It was held that the defendant was entitled not only 
 to retain the money paid on account but to recover the balance., 
 {Chandler v. Webster, 1904, 1 K. B. 493, 73 L. J. K. B. 401.) 
 But if the price is not payable or the performance is not due 
 until after the time when the impossibility arises, it cannot be 
 claimed. (Kr&ll v. Henry, 1903, 2 K. B. 740, 72 L. J. K. B. 
 
 794.) 
 
 And when the existence of a particular state of things is merely 
 the inducement to one party to enter into the contract but is not 
 the basis of the contract between the two parties the doctrine of 
 Taylor v. Caldwell does not apply. 
 
 The defendant hired a steamer for the purpose of taking paying 
 passengers to see a Naval Review and for a day's cruise round the 
 Fleet. Owing to the King's illness the Naval Review had to be 
 abandoned, but it was held that this did not excuse the defendant 
 from his liability to pay the price agreed upon for the steamer. 
 
 (Heme Bay Stmmboat Company v. Hutton, 1903, 2 K. B. 
 683, 72 L. J. K. B. 879.) 
 
 It must be admitted that the distinction between this case and 
 such cases as Krell v. Henry is very difficult. (See Anson, Con- 
 tracts, 14th ed. p. 387; Pollock, Contracts, 8th ed. p. 440; 
 Leake, Contracts, 6th ed. p. 500. 
 
 In English law war does not in itself necessarily create 
 impossibility of performance. 
 
 Save in cases governed by the principle above stated, the out- 
 break of war is not admitted in English law as an event preventing 
 the performance of a contract unless the war creates an impossi- 
 bility in law, as when trading with the enemy is prohibited, or 
 unless the war renders the carrying out of the contract once for 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 325 
 
 all impossible, and from the nature of the contract it appears that 
 the intention of the parties was to make the contract conditional 
 on its performance continuing to be possible in fact. (See Leiston 
 Gas Co. v. Leiston-cum-Sizeivell Urban Council, 1916, 2 K. B. 
 428, 85 L. J. K. B. 1759; Horlock v. Bed, 1916, A. C. 486, 
 85 L. J. K. B. 602; supra, p. 322.) 
 
 But the danger to a ship of capture by the enemy may be an 
 excuse for a deviation, and j)erhaps it might entitle the ship to 
 discharge her cargo in a different port from that named' in the 
 contract. (See The Teidonia, 1872, L. R. 4 P. C. 171, 41 L. J. 
 Adm. 57; Pole v. Cetcovitch, 1860, 9 C. B. N. S. 430, 127 
 R. R. 705; Carver, Carriage by Sea, 5th ed. s. 290; Baty and 
 Morgan, War, Its Conduct and Legal Results, p. 414.) 
 
 There have been many English cases since the outbreak of war, 
 and the tendency of the courts is to apply the rule strictly that 
 the outbreak or the continuance of war does not in principle 
 excuse the defendant from performing his contract. 
 
 Thus, where a residential flat in England had been let before 
 the war for a term of years to an Austrian subject, and after the 
 outbreak of war, he was prohibited by law from residing in that 
 area, it was held that this did not terminate the lease. His per- 
 sonal residence in the flat was not the " foundation of the contract." 
 (London and Northern Estates Co. v. Kish-Schlesinger, 1916, 
 1 K. B. 20, 85 L. J. K. B. 369.) 
 
 In what is now the leading case it was necessary to consider 
 the legal effect upon a charter-party of the requisition of the ship 
 hy the Government. A steamer had been chartered for five years 
 from December, 1912, the charterers having liberty to sublet the 
 steamer. She was requisitioned by the British Government in 
 February, 1915, for use as a transport. No one could say how 
 long she would be required. It was held that the charter-party 
 remained in force. (F . A. Tamplin Steamship Co., Ltd. v. 
 Anglo-Mexican Petroleum Products Co., Ltd., 1916, 2 A. C. 
 397, 85 L. J. K. B. 1389. Supra, p. 323. See the cases to the 
 end of 1916 collected and discussed in Campbell, H., Law of War 
 and Contract; Mackinnon, F. D., Effect of War on Contract.) 
 
 Statutory power to avoid contracts. 
 
 In England by a recent amendment to the law, the Board of 
 Trade has power to order that a contract with an enemy shall be 
 cancelled either unconditionally or upon such conditions as the 
 
32(3 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Board may think fit if the Board considers that the contract is 
 injurious to the public interest. {Trading with the Enemy 
 Amendment Act, 1916 (5 & 6 'Geo. 5, c. 105), s. 2.) # 
 
 Force majeure compared with " act of God." 
 
 The liability in the English law of the common carrier of goods 
 whether by land or by sea is wider than that of the French law. 
 In the English law carriers are, in the absence of express stipula- 
 tions to the contrary, when such stipulations are lawful, absolutely 
 responsible for the loss of the goods unless they can prove that 
 it was due to the Kings enemies, or the act of God, or that it 
 was caused by inherent vice or by the negligence of the shipper. 
 (Peek v. North Staffordshire Railway Co., 1863, 10 H. L. C. 
 ,473, 32 L. J. Q. B. 241.) And the "act of God" means that 
 the act must have been caused by the elementary forces of nature 
 as opposed to the act of man. 
 
 In a leading English case, James, L. J., thus expresses it: 
 " The ' act of God ' is merely a short way of expressing this pro- 
 position: a common carrier is not liable for any accident as to 
 which he can show that it was due to natural causes directly and 
 exclusively, without human intervention, and that it could not 
 have been prevented by any amount of foresight, pains and 
 care reasonably to be expected from him." (Nugent v. 
 Smith, 1876, 1 C. P. D. 423, at p. 444, 45 L. J. C. P. 697. 
 
 Tho question is not whether the accident could have been pre- 
 vented by any conceivable care, but whether it could have been 
 prevented by such care as was reasonable in the circumstances. 
 (See, for illustrations, Beven, Negligence, 3rd ed. 1, p. 81, and 
 2, p. 879; Pollock, Torts, 10th ed. p. 513; Salmond, Twts, 
 4th ed. p. 232.) 
 
 "Act of God" is a much narrower ' term than cas fort ait, 
 because cas fortuit includes many accidents which are caused either 
 in whole or in part by the agency of man. A loss caused by fir© 
 is not due to the act of God unless the fire was caused by lightning. 
 (See Gatliff v. Bourne, 1838, 4 Bing. N. C. 314, 3 M. & G. 643, 
 44 R. R. 714.) 
 
 And loss by theft committed by a third party for whom the 
 carrier is not responsible, or loss caused by the negligence of such 
 ;i third party, is held in the French law to be due to a cas fortuit, 
 but in the English law it would not be regarded as the " act of 
 God." (See on the distinction between "act of God" and cas 
 
NON-PERFORMANCE WITHOUT FAULT OF DEBTOR. 327 
 
 ■fori nil, Nugent v. Smith, ut supra; Carver, Carriage, by Sea, 
 5th eel. p. 7; Holmes, Common Law, Lecture V, p. 201.) 
 
 One of the arguments used by the French writers who think 
 that the carrier oug'ht to be responsible for loss caused by accidents 
 such as are inherent in that business is that the English law holds 
 him liable unless the loss was caused by the " act of God." (See 
 Josserand, Les Transports, n. 582.) This may be a good reason 
 for changing the French law, but it cannot affect the interpretation 
 of the code. 
 
 The English law restricts the freedom of the carrier to limit 
 his liability by contract, but this subject cannot be treated here. 
 The liability of innkeepers for loss or injury to goods belonging 
 to a guest is in England governed by statute. The Act provides 
 that the innkeeper's liability shall be limited to thirty pounds 
 unless the goods have been stolen, lost, or injured through the 
 wilful act or neglect of himself or his servants, or the goods have 
 been deposited with him for safe custody. But the innkeeper 
 does not enjoy the privilege unless he exhibits the Act in a con- 
 spicuous part of the entrance to the inn. (26 & 27 Vict. c. 41. 
 See, for cases, Beven, Negligence, 3rd ed. 2. pp. 856 seq.) 
 
328 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XVII. 
 
 CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 
 Different kinds of obligations. 
 
 The chief kinds of obligations are conditional obligations, obli- 
 gations with a term, alternative obligations, facultative obliga- 
 tions, joint obligations, joint and several obligations, divisible 
 and indivisible obligations, and obligations with a penal clause. 
 
 The expression " condition " is sometimes used to describe any 
 term of a contract, as when a charge laid upon a donee is spoken 
 of as a "condition" of the gift. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 743; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 94, note 1.) 
 
 But when we speak of a conditional obligation the word " con- 
 dition " has a more technical sense. An obligation is conditional 
 when it is made to depend upon an event future and uncertain, 
 either by suspending it until the event happens or by dissolving 
 it according as the event does or does not happen., (C. C. F. 
 1168; C. C. Q. 1079.) 
 
 The Egyptian codes vary the language but not the sense, sub- 
 ject to what is said later as to the word " or." 
 
 They state: An obligation may depend on a future or un- 
 certain event, the occurrence of which shall bring it info existence 
 or confirm it/or shall prevent its coming into existence or extin- 
 guish it. (C. C. E. 103/157.) In the first case the condition 
 is called suspensive, and in the second resolutive. For example, 
 a seller may sell an article subject to the condition that it is not 
 to become the property of the buyer until the price has been paid 
 in full. Here the sale is subject to a suspensive condition. Or 
 he may sell it subject to the condition that he is to have the right 
 of buying it back at the same price within a year. Here the. 
 condition is resolutive. 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 'Y29 
 
 Suspensive condition. 
 
 When the condition is suspensive it is as yet uncertain whether 
 the person to whom the right is given conditionally will ever be 
 able to enforce it. But, pending the settlement of this question, 
 the possibility of the right emerging alters the situation of the 
 parties, and the eventual right of the creditor is in certain ways 
 protected. 
 
 Resolutive condition. 
 
 When the condition is resolutive the right is acquired at the 
 date of the contract, but it is uncertain if the creditor will be 
 entitled to keep it. Thus, if an article is sold on condition that 
 the seller shall have a right of redemption, that is, that the buyer 
 shall be bound to resell the prioperty to the seller if he demands 
 it within a certain delay, there is a resolutive condition. This 
 distinction between the suspensive and the resolutive condition 
 does not go to the root of the matter/ 
 
 In reality, as Ulpian says, there is always a suspensive con- 
 dition, but the question is whether it prevents the right coming 
 into existence, or allows it to come into existence but may put an 
 end to it afterwards. An obligation with a resolutive condition 
 is in reality an obligation pure and simple which, subject to a 
 certain suspensive condition, may be resolved. D. 18. 2. 2; 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 772.) Sale subject to 
 the condition that the property does not pass until payment of 
 the price, is perhaps the most familiar example of the suspensive, 
 condition, and, in this case, the condition is frequently implied. 
 
 A true condition takes effect only when the obligation depends 
 upon something which has yet to happen, and it has five charac- 
 teristics:—'!) the event must be future; (2) it must be uncer- 
 tain; (3) it must be possible; (4) it must be legal; (5) it must 
 not be destructive of the tie of the obligation. Taking these 
 points in their order. 
 
 (1) Event must not have already occurred. 
 
 When an obligation depends on an event which has actually 
 happened, but this fact is unknown to the parties, it is not con- 
 ditional. The obligation takes effect or is defeated from the time 
 at which it is contracted. For example, I sell you on August 1st 
 a cargo of wheat on my steamer provided the ship arrives safely 
 
330 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 in Liverpool. On August 1st the steamer was already in dock 
 at Liverpool, though this fact is unknown to both of us. 
 
 There is nothing- here to suspend the obligation. It is either 
 an unconditional sale or it is no sale at all. We may possibly not 
 hear for some time on what day the vessel arrived in Liverpool, 
 but as soon as this fact is known, it becomes clear that there was 
 an immediate sale on August 1st, and the risk, according to the 
 French law, passed to you at that date. The Egyptian law differs 
 as regards the passing of the risk. (C. C. E. 297/371. Infra, 
 p. 480.) On the other hand, if, on August 1st, unknown to 
 both of us, the steamer was at the bottom of the Atlantic, there 
 is likewise no condition, because when this fact is ascertained it 
 becomes clear that there never was a sale at all, for at the date of 
 the agreement the object about which the parties were contracting 
 had ceased to exist. This was the Roman law and it has been 
 followed in the French law. (Inst. 3. 15. 6; Pothier, Obliga- 
 tions, n. 202; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 97. 
 
 The Egyptian Code, however, does not say, as the French Code 
 does, that the event upon which the obligation depends must be 
 " future and uncertain." (C. C. F. 1168.) It uses the disjunc- 
 tive, and says "future or uncertain." (C. C. E. 103/157.; 
 
 But, probably, this is by mere inadvertence. An event which 
 has happened cannot make a condition in any ordinary sense. It 
 is the opinion of Fathi Pasha Zaghlool that the Egyptian legis- 
 lator did not intend to change the law. (Commentary, in Arabic, 
 on C. C. E. p. 14.) Mr. Halton suggests that "perhaps the 
 Egyptian legislator wished to employ language which would allow 
 a past but unverified event to be considered as a condition. But 
 the unusual drafting of the Egyptian article may simply be an 
 inadvertence." (1, p. 281.) The Mixed Court seems to take 
 the latter view. (C. A. Alex, ler mai 1907, B.L.J. XIX, 232.) 
 
 (2) Event future but certain. 
 
 There is no condition when the future event is certain though 
 the date when it will take place may be uncertain. The obliga- 
 tion in that case is not subject to a condition. It is an obligation, 
 with a term, and its character will be explained later under that 
 head. For example, a policy of life-assurance is not a condi- 
 tional obligation, it is an absolute obligation, because the assured 
 will die sooner or later. It may, however, contain obligations 
 which are truly conditional, such as, to par the sum in the policy 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 331 
 
 if the assured shall attain the age of sixty, because this is an 
 event which is both future and uncertain. 
 
 (3) Event impossible. 
 
 The event must be possible. An obligation which is made to 
 depend upon the doing or happening of a thing' which is impos- 
 sible is void. 
 
 If I say, "I will give you L. E. 5,000 if you will jump ovei 
 the moon," I know that I am not taking any risk, and it is 
 immaterial whether the condition is that I or you or a third party 
 should do the impossible. 
 
 It is generally agreed that by "impossible," the code means 
 impossible for anybody. 
 
 A promise made, subject to a condition that the promisor or the 
 promisee or a third party shall not do something which it is 
 impossible for anybody to do, does not annul the obligation, be- 
 cause as it is certain that the condition can never be performed, 
 the promise is really an unconditional one. If I promise you 
 L. E. 1,000 if you do not jump over the moon this is an absolute 
 promise in spite of its form, for it is evident that you cannot 
 perform the condition. The French Code contains an express 
 provision to this effect. (C. C. F. 1173.; But this article is 
 useless, because the obligation is of necessity absolute and the 
 apparent condition is not one in reality, since it lacks the essential 
 quality of being uncertain. (Aub'ry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 97; 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 181; Req. 8 janv. 1894. D. 94. 1. 128.) 
 
 (4) Event unlawful. 
 
 The condition must be legal. The French Code says: Every 
 condition contrarij to law, or inconsistent with good morals, is 
 void and renders void the obligation ivhich depend* upon it. 
 (C. C. F. 1172; Cass. 27 avril 1906, D. 1907. 1. 97; Req. 8 
 janv. 1894, D. 94. 1. 128.) No damages can be recovered for 
 the breach of such a contract. 
 
 A promise to pay money to a man if he commits a crime or 
 does something illegal or immoral is not binding; and, according 
 to what seems to be the better opinion, a stipulation that a man 
 shall forfeit a certain sum if he does something illegal is likewise 
 null, though some writers think it ought to be supported as 
 encouraging morality. But the sufficient answer to this is that 
 given by Pothier, that it is contrary to good morals to allow a 
 
332 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 man to stipulate for a reward for abstaining from an act from 
 which it is his duty to abstain in any event. (Oblig. n. 204;, 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 764; supra, I, p. 116.) The various kinds 
 of unlawful contracts have been already discussed in speaking 
 of the cause of obligations. In regard to impossible and unlawful 
 conditions there is an important difference in the French law 
 between wills or donations and onerous contracts. Such condi- 
 tions in a will are considered as not written. The legatee takes 
 the bequest and the condition is read out of the will. (C. C. F. 
 900.) 
 
 And the same rule applies to impossible or illegal conditions 
 attached to a gift inter vivos. 
 
 The French Code allows the donee to take the gift free of the 
 condition, in the same way as a legatee takes a legacy. (C. C. F. 
 900; Baudry-Lacant. et Colin, Des Donations, 1, n. 65: B.-L. 
 et Barde, 2, n. 753.) 
 
 But according to the French jurisprudence, this is a question 
 of interpretation. The rule that the condition shall be held pro 
 non scripta, i.e., that the legatee shall take the legacy free of the 
 condition, does not apply when the condition was la cause impul- 
 sive et determimmte cle la liberalite. (Req. 12 mai 1909, D. 
 1910. 1. 291; Cass. 19 oct. 1910, D. 1911. 1. 463. Cf. Lyon, 
 28 juill. 1904, D. 1908. 2. 30.) 
 
 (5) Event left to free choice of promisor. 
 
 The condition must not be destructive of the tie of the obli- 
 gation. 
 
 The French Code says: Toute obligation est nulle lorsqu'eMe 
 a ete contractee sons une condition potestative de la part cle cclui 
 qui s' oblige. (C. C. F. 1174.) This means that an obligation 
 conditional on the will purely of the party promising is void. 
 But if the condition consists in the doing or not doing of a certain 
 act, although such act be dependent on his will, the obligation is 
 valid. 
 
 It is clear that if I say " I will pay you so much if I choose," 
 there is no obligation; I am as free as I was before. On the other 
 hand, if I say " I will pay so much if I do a certain thing, as, 
 for example, if I set up a certain kind of business in a particular 
 locality; or if I promise to pay so much " unless Ldo something," 
 my will is no longer free; I can do or not do the thing in question, 
 but I incur a penalty if I exercise my choice in a certain way. 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 333 
 
 Where the debtor has left himself perfectly free, by saying he is 
 only to be bound if he shall choose, this is called a potestative 
 condition, but it is in truth not a condition at all. It must not 
 be forgotten that in a synallagmatic contract one party may be 
 bound though the other is not bound, because his obligation is 
 purely potestative. (Pand. Frang. Oblig. n. 1113; Cas^. 25 
 now 1896, D. 97. 1. 34; Reg. v. Dem&rs, 1900, A. C. 10 -J. 
 69 L. J . P. C. 5.) For instance, in the common case of an option 
 of sale, I promise to sell a thing to you at a certain price within 
 a certain delay if you declare your acceptance. I am bound, 
 subject to the condition, but you are free to take it or not. 
 (Pothier, Vente, n. 478; Pand. Frang. vo. Oblig. n. 1114.) 
 
 Nor is there anything to prevent an obligation being formed 
 which is dissoluble at the will of one of the parties. 
 
 This is so, for example, in a sale subject to the right of redemp- 
 tion, or in a lease which, according to its terms, may be broken at 
 certain dates. (Larombiere, on art. 1174, n. 17.) So there is 
 nothing to prevent a clause in a contract with an employee that 
 he may be dismissed at pleasure. The contract is valid till the 
 power of terminating it is exercised, and a clause which permits 
 the power does not make the contract purely potestative. (Limoges, 
 11 juill. 1898, D. 1901. 2. 380.) 
 
 For instance, the director of a theatre may reserve to himself 
 the right to resiliate the contract with an actor at the end of a 
 month, though no corresponding right is given to the actor. (Cass. 
 2 mai 1900, D. 1900. 1. 392.) 
 
 It is sometimes a difficult question of interpretation to decide 
 whether the condition is purely potestative, that is to say, if it is 
 merely the equivalent of " I bind myself if I choose "—si mlum>. 
 (See Cass. 15 Janvier 1890, D. 91. 1. 30; Trib. Civ. Marseille, 
 21 nov. 1896, sous Eeq. 9 janv. 1900, D. 1903. 1. 321, and 
 note; C. A. Alex. 3 juin 1896, B. L. J. VIII, 313. Pothier 
 argues that a promise to pay " if I judge it reasonable " is not a 
 potestative condition because my judgment can be controlled by 
 the courts. (Oblig. n. 48.) But this reasoning is rightly rejected. 
 
 Such a clause would leave me the sole judge of what was 
 reasonable . 
 
 It would be otherwise if the condition were " if it is reason- 
 able." (Demolombe, 25, n. 318. See Lyon, 10 mars 1864, D. 
 64. 5. 255.) In a recent French case A sold to B the sole right of 
 manufacturing a certain product in consideration of receiving a 
 certain sum per kilogramme of the product sold. It was eon- 
 
334 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 tended that this was a potestative condition, as the buyer might 
 reduce the manufacture to zero, but the Court of Cassation did 
 not take this view. They hold it was an implied term of tho 
 contract that the buyer should produce as much of the article as 
 was sufficient to supply the demand. (Cass. 5 mai 1905, D. 
 1906. 1. 360. 
 
 A condition to pay to an employee in addition to his salary a 
 bonus of a certain percentage, " subject to the recommendation of 
 the management," does not leave them free to give it or not by 
 ii re caprice. If they do not recommend the bonus they must 
 allege good reasons for not doing so. (Gravel Lumber Co. v. 
 ■ ote, 1908. R. J. Q. 17 K. B. 398.) 
 
 Is a promise to pay "'when I choose" potestative? Pothier 
 held that it was, but the prevailing opinion is that this is not the 
 presumed intention. (Oblig. n. 47.) The debtor means to bind 
 himself, but to reserve liberty to execute his contract any time 
 before his death. But if he dies without executing it, the payment 
 becomes at once exigible from his heirs. (Toullier, 6. n. 498; 
 Larombiere, on art. 1174, n. 4; Pand. Franc. Oblig. n. 1083. 
 See Cass. 21 aout 1850, D. 50. 1. 346.) 
 
 On similar principles, such conditions as " when I shall have the 
 means," "when I shall sell the property," etc., are generally con- 
 sidered not to be purely potestative. In the first case the court 
 might be called upon to decide whether the debtor was in a posi- 
 tion to fulfil the contract, and in the second case the debtor is 
 bound if he decides to sell, so that .his will is not entirely free. 
 Larombiere, on art. 1174, n. 5 et n. 7; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 134; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 969; Paris, 19 nov. 1912, D. 1913. 
 2. 126.) 
 
 The presumption is against the creditor having left the debtor 
 free to perform the obligation or not. (C. A. Alex. 22 fevr. 1900, 
 B. L.J. XII, 126.) 
 
 A condition is not purely potestative, but is said to be mixed 
 when it depends partly on the will of the parties and partly on tho 
 will of a third party. C. C. F. 1171.) For example, "if you 
 marry my cousin Mary.' In this case you may do your best, but 
 the issue is not wholly within your power. In the Roman law 
 and iii the old French law there was an important distinction 
 between such a condition in a contract and in a legacy. If tho 
 condition was in a legacy it was enough if the legatee did his pari . 
 If it was no fault of his that the condition was not fulfilled he g it. 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 335 
 
 the legacy, whereas if such a condition were in a contract its 
 fulfilment was a sme qua mm. 
 
 Pothier accepted this distinction. >Ohlig. nos. "213, 214.) But 
 the modern French law has rejected it. If such a condition is 
 imposed, whether it bo in a will or in a contract, it is a pure 
 question of interpretation whether the intention was to make the 
 fulfilment of the condition an absolute sine qua mm, or if the 
 intention was merely to impose upon the party the duty of doing 
 his best to fulfil it. 
 
 C. C. F. 1175 states that every condition must be fulfilled in the 
 way that the parties probably intended. Even in a contract it 
 may appear that the intention was merely that the parties should 
 do their best. (Paris, 4 fevr. 1891, D. 91. 2. 317.) And in a 
 legacy the courts will be more inclined to give a favourable con- 
 struction, that is, one which will make the legacy effectual, unless 
 the terms of the will show plainly that the testator meant to make 
 the fulfilment of the condition a sine qua non of the payment of 
 the legacy. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Ohlicj. 2, n. 795; Mont- 
 pellier, 26 dec. 1892, D. 94. 2. 284.) 
 
 There are many cases in which conditions are implied, some- 
 times because this is the presumed intention of the parties, and 
 sometimes because the law says that a condition shall be implied. 
 For instance, in a contract with a photographer it is an implied 
 condition that he shall not sell copies of the photograph without 
 the consent of the sitter. The provisions made in a marriage 
 contract are all conditional on the marriage taking place. In 
 every synallagmatic contract the condition is implied that a party 
 who is himself in breach of the contract cannot call upon the 
 other party to perform his part. Many other illustrations might 
 be given, but this subject belongs rather to the interpretation of 
 contract than to the law of conditional obligations, and has been 
 discussed under that head. (Supra, L, pp. 378 seq.) 
 
 Effects of the condition. 
 Conditional right is not mere hope. 
 
 The code deals with the effects of the condition in a somewhat 
 fragmentary manner. 
 
 The French Code says, indirectly, that pending the condition 
 the obligation is "suspended.'' (0. C. F. 1185.) It might be 
 inferred from this that pending the condition the parties were as 
 before, and that the obligation produced no effect at all until the 
 
336 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 condition either happened or failed. On the other hand, the code 
 gays: // the creditor be dead- before the fulfilment of the con- 
 dition his rights pass to his heir. (C. C. F. 1179.) 
 
 How can any "rights" exist if the obligation is suspended? 
 Pothier, following the language of Justinian's Institutes, says: 
 " Pending the condition there is nothing as yet due, but there is 
 only a hope that it will be due." (Inst. 3. 15. 4- ObUq 
 n. 218.) 
 
 But in other passages the Roman lawyers recognise that there 
 is more than a spes, and they use the expression creditor of 
 the party entitled conditionally. (D. 44. 7. 42.; The language 
 of the French Code shows that the codifiers take the view that 
 there is a right and not merely a hope. They use the word 
 "rights." (O. C. F. 1179, 1180.) If we compare a right with a 
 hope the difference is clear. A person who has no legal claim to 
 succeed to a share of another's estate at his death may have a very 
 reasonable expectation of doing so. The other person may have 
 encouraged him in this belief. But such an expectation is a mere 
 spes. It is indeterminate as to amount; it is not an asset which, 
 the expectant heir can deal with in any way, and he cannot take 
 any steps to protect it. In all these respects the " right " of the 
 conditional creditor is different. It is true he may never realise 
 it, for the condition may. fail, but in the meantime it is a deter- 
 minate value which is an asset of his estate and can be dealt with 
 by him. It passes to his heirs, if not assigned inter vivos, and 
 it may be protected by conservatory acts. It is better, therefore, to" 
 speak of it as a conditional " right," or a right which exists in 
 germ. (Laurent, 17, n. 87; Demolombe, 25, n. 356; Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 838; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 183.) 
 
 Nothing yet due pending the condition. 
 
 Pending the condition nothing is payable, and, therefore, if the 
 conditional debtor has paid in error he has the action for repetition. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 218; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Obliq. 2 r 
 n. 832.) 
 
 This is not so in the case of obligation with a term. The debtor 
 who has paid a debt which is not yet due under the mistaken 
 impression that it was due cannot repeat it in the French law. 
 (C. C. F. 1186; B.-L. et Barde, Olig. 2, n. 987.) 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 3,'}7 
 
 Conditional creditor may do conservatory acts. 
 
 Tho conditional creditor may take conservatory measures, and 
 what these may be will depend upon the nature of his conditional 
 debt. Thus he may bring actions to obtain an acknowledgment of 
 his right, or to interrupt prescription, or to preserve evidence. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Tissier, De la Prescription, nos. 394 — 397.) 
 
 He may claim to be present at a partition, and may attack a 
 partition as in fraud of his rights. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 222; 
 Pintd. Franc. Oblig. n. 1252.) But. he cannot bring the Paulian 
 action nor the direct action, for these are more than conservatory 
 measures. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 629; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4. p. 216, note 1, bis; D. N. C. C. art. 1167, n. 274.) 
 
 If the conditional debtor is administering the property in such 
 a manner as to endanger the conditional right, the creditor may 
 apply for an injunction against his so doing and ask that the 
 damages already suffered should be judicially ascertained, though 
 they will only be payable if the condition should be fulfilled. In 
 a strong case the court might even order sequestration of the pro- 
 perty, as, for example, if the object of the obligation was to 
 deliver a wood, and the conditional debtor were to begin cutting 
 it down, or if it was to deliver a house and the conditional debtor 
 was demolishing it. (Demolombe, 25, n. 372; Larombiere, on 
 art. 1180, n. 5.) 
 
 Conditional creditor's right protected if conditional debtor 
 
 is insolvent. 
 
 The conditional creditor cannot do any execution on the goods 
 of the debtor, but if execution is done by other creditors whose 
 claims are unconditional, the conditional creditor must be pro- 
 tected. He cannot claim to take a dividend, for the condition may 
 fail, but his chance must be preserved. This may be done either 
 by consigning the amount and waiting till it is seen if the condi- 
 tion is fulfilled, or by dividing the whole estate, but making the 
 creditors find security to repay the amount which will be due to 
 the conditional creditor if the condition is fulfilled. (Pothier, 
 Oblig. n. 222; Larombiere, on art. 1180, n. 3; Baudry-Lacant. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 843.) Pending the condition the conditional 
 creditor may alienate the thing or create real rights over it, but 
 these acts will produce no effect unless the condition should be 
 fulfilled. If, however, this should bo the case they will be effectual 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 22 
 
338 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 from their date. (CO. F. 2125; C. C. Q. 2038; Demolombe, 25, 
 n. 381.) 
 
 Conditional seller may revindicate if condition fails. 
 
 If in a sale subject to a suspensive condition the condition 
 should fail, the seller can claim back the goods. 
 
 So if goods are sold subject to the condition that they shall not 
 Income the property of the purchaser until the price is paid, the 
 seller can revindicate them if the condition fails, unless the buyer* 
 is protected by the rule possession vwit litre. (O. A. Alex. 4 dec. 
 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 31.) 
 
 Where the sale in such cases is for a price payable by instal- 
 ments, and the seller revindicates the thing, he must give back the 
 instalments received, unless there is a stipulation that the instal- 
 ments shall be considered to be the equivalent of rent, and that the 
 seller shall be entitled to retain them, or unless such an intention 
 appears from the term's of the contract. Such a stipulation is, 
 however, generally inserted in these contracts. (See Dall. Supp. 
 Write, n. 16; Req. 21 juill. 1897, D. 98. 1. 269; D. N. O. O. 
 art. 1582, nos. 22 seq. ; Cass. 29 janv. 1902, S. 1902. 1. 168; 
 Cass. 22 dec. 1909, S. 1910. 1. 191.) 
 
 The rule that the conditional creditor cannot give a better right 
 than he has himself is greatly limited by the provisions of law 
 for the protection of purchasers of moveables in good faith. 
 (C. C. E. 607, 608/733, 734.) If the conditional debtor b©- 
 •eomes insolvent, and the conditional creditor owes him money on 
 another account, he can refuse to pay this until it is seen if the 
 condition will be fulfilled, and this conduct will be regarded as a 
 conservatory act. An owner whose right is subject to a resolutive 
 condition can only give rights subject to the same condition, 
 though, in the case of moveables, the purchaser in good faith may 
 be protected otherwise by the rule possession vaut titre. 
 
 The fulfilment and the failure of conditions. 
 
 When an obligation has been contracted subject to the con- 
 dition that an event shall occur within a fixed time, this condition 
 is considered to have failed when the time has expired without 
 the event occurring. If no lime was fixed, the condition may 
 always be fulfill-ed, and it is not considered as having failed until 
 it has become certain that the ere, it will not occur. 
 
 When ait obligation is contracted subject to the condition 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 339 
 
 that cm event will not happen within a fixed time, such condition 
 is fulfilled by the expiration of the time without th< event hmmig 
 occurred. It is fulfilled equally if, before the time has expired, 
 it becomes certain tJmt the event will not happen. If there be 
 no time fixed, the condition is not deemed to be fulfilled, until 
 it is certain that the event will not happen. (C. C. F. 
 1176, 1177.) For example I contract an obligation subject to the 
 condition, "If ray daughter docs not get married within two 
 years." If the two years expire without her marrying, or if she 
 dies within that period, the condition is fulfilled. Thus if the 
 condition is " if you marry," you may fulfil it at any time before 
 your death, for it is not certain until then that the condition may 
 not be fulfilled. But if the condition is " if you do not deliver to 
 mo a determinate thing within two years," and two years elapse 
 without your having made delivery, the condition is fulfilled. 
 And, equally so, if within the two years the thing" has perished, 
 for then it is certain that you cannot deliver it. (C. C. F. 1176, 
 1177; Pothier, Oblig. 209, 210.) The question if a condition has 
 been fulfilled in the manner contemplated by the parties is one for 
 the court to decide according to the circumstances of each par- 
 ticular case. (Eeq. 2 aoiit 1909, D. 1912. 1. 55.) 
 
 These rules are more obscurely expressed in the Egyptian Code: 
 // the, eiv'ent provided for is or becomes certain and the condi- 
 tion is resolutory, the obligation shall be void or be avoided; if, 
 in the like Cases, the condition is suspensive, such condition shall 
 be considered never to have existed. (C. C. E. 104/158.) 
 
 Conditions strictly interpreted. 
 
 Conditions are strictly construed and must be performed in 
 forma specified. Unless there is something in the terms of the 
 contract, taken in connection with the circumstances, which shows 
 that the party who stipulated the condition did not intend that it 
 must be fulfilled literally, the court is not entitled to introduce any 
 equitable extensions or modifications. For instance, if the condi- 
 tion is "if you marry, within two years," you do not fulfil it by 
 m;! irying the day after the term has expired. You cannot plead 
 that you were not put. in default, or that you were in prison, or 
 that you were insane and could not marry within the time. 
 
 The .simple question is was the condition fulfilled, and tjhe 
 court has no right to consider any possible excuse for non-fulfil- 
 ment. This rigour, be it always understood, will give way when 
 
 oo •) 
 
340 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 it does not appear to have been intended by the parties. Thus, to 
 take Pothier's very simple illustration, the condition " if you give 
 the 100 gold louis " may very well be fulfilled by your giving 
 their value in other currency, unless there is reason to think special 
 importance was attached to payment in gold. (Oblig. n. 206; 
 Laurent, 17, n. 73; Demolombe, 25, n. 330; B.-L. et Barde, 2,. 
 n. 790.) 
 
 Condition that act shall be performed by particular person. 
 
 The same considerations apply to performance by a particular 
 person. If the act is one of a personal character it can only be- 
 performed by the particular person whom the stipulant had in 
 view. The condition "if you paint my portrait," or "if you 
 write a sonnet," can only be fulfilled by you. You cannot sub- 
 stitute another painter or poet, though his skill may be greater- 
 than yours. On the other hand, if the act is one which can be 
 performed in the same manner and equally well by any competent 
 person, the presumption is that the stipulant did not intend to. 
 insist on the other party doing it himself. For instance, " if you 
 cut down a tree on your land which blocks my view " is a type of 
 conditions of this kind. It is not intended that you should cut it 
 down in person, but that you or your heirs should get it cut down. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 207; Pand. Fmng. Oblig. n. 1151; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 2, n. 791.) 
 
 What if no time is fixed for performance? 
 
 If no time is fixed by the parties, a time cannot be fixed by the 
 court unless this appears to have been the intention of the parties. 
 Pothier suggests two exceptions to this rule, and there has been 
 some controversy with regard to them: (1) According to Pothier,. 
 when the condition consists in the other party doing something, 
 and no time is fixed for the performance, the court maj r fix a 
 reasonable time, and hold that the condition has failed if the fulfil- 
 ment does not take place within the delay so fixed. Thus, for 
 example, I promise a sum to my neighbour if he cuts down a tree 
 which blocks my view . If he does not cut down the tree within a 
 reasonable time, I may bring an action asking the court to fix a 
 delay within which he must cut down the tree, or, failing his 
 doing so, to declare mo free of my obligation for the future. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 209.) It would seem, in this ease, that this 
 is the implied intention of the parties. I could hardly have in- 
 tended that if at any time, even a hundred years hence, the heirs of" 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 341 
 
 my neighbour cut down the tree, my heirs should be bound to pay 
 the sum which I had promised. 
 
 Many French writers accept the view of Pothier. (Demo- 
 lombe, 25, n. 348; Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 96, bis II. In this 
 sense, Grenoble, 7 janv. 1873, D. 73. 2. 108.) But, according 
 to other writers, articles 1176 and 1177 of the French Code must 
 be literally applied, and they do not allow the court power to fix 
 any delay unless there is evidence that this was intended by the 
 parties. (Laurent, 17, n. 75.) MM. Baudry-Lacantinerie et 
 Barde hold that when the condition is a negative potestative con- 
 dition, for example, to pay a sum if I do not cut down a tree, it is 
 implied that I am to do it in a reasonable time. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 •2, n. 800.) 
 
 Tinder the Egyptian Code there is less difficulty in accepting the 
 view of Pothier, because that code does not contain an express 
 provision like that of C. C. F.'ll76: S'il riy a point de temps 
 fixe, la condition petit toujours etre accomplie. 
 
 (2) Similarly, if the condition were that my neighbour had 
 promised me a certain sum if he did not cut down the tree, the 
 intention of the parties here is clearly that this shall be done within 
 a reasonable delay. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 211.) 
 
 But if I promise a sum to a man on condition that he does an act 
 of a personal kind, as, for example, if I promise a sum to a 
 painter on condition that he paints my portrait, it would seem, 
 under the French Code, that he could claim the payment if he 
 painted the portrait at any time before his death. It is possible 
 to suppose that the parties intended to leave the painter free to 
 choose his own time, and there cannot be any question of the 
 liability of heirs. It would seem, therefore, that the article in the 
 French Code must be given its literal effect. (C. C. F. 1176; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 1. c.) Here also, in the silence of the Egyptian 
 Code, it seems possible to reach a better solution by adopting the 
 view advocated by Pothier. 
 
 Fraudulent prevention of fulfilment. 
 
 The French Code has an important article: La condition est 
 reputee accomplie lorsque c'est le debiteur, oblige sous cette con- 
 dition, qui en a empeohe V accompUssement . (C. C. F. 1178.) 
 This was borrowed from the Roman law and is obviously equi- 
 table. It might rest on either of two principles: (1) that damage 
 was wrongfully caused by the promisor in depriving the promisee 
 
342 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 of the chance of the condition being fulfilled; or (2) that a party 
 by whose fault the fulfilment of the condition has been prevented 
 cannot take advantage of his own fault, or, in other words, is- 
 estopped from pleading the non-fulfilment for which he is himself 
 to blame. 
 
 The first explanation is the one. which is traditional in the 
 French law. (See Big-ot-Preameneu, in Locre, 12, n. 63, p. 339; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 802.) And, seeing that it is a case of re- 
 paration, the general rule applies that there must be fault to create 
 liability. It is not necessary that there should be an intention to 
 prevent the fulfilment, but there must be, at least, negligence 
 which makes the fulfilment impossible. (Cass. 6 aout 1866, S. 
 66.' 1. 397, Journal du Palais, 66, p. 1074.) 
 
 So the principle does not apply when the debtor's obligation is 
 potestative. If he is free to do or not to do a certain thing his not 
 doing it cannot be imputed to him as a fault. (Pothier, 1. c; 
 Laurent, 17, n. 76; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 803.) 
 
 So if I undertake to sell you my house " if I should leave Cairo," 
 my not leaving Cairo is no fault . A party who merely by using 
 his legal right prevents the fulfilment of the condition does not 
 fall under this article. Pothier gives this example: a testator 
 leaves a house to a legatee on condition that within a year the 
 legatee pays a certain sum to B. 
 
 The heir, who is a creditor of the legatee, seizes his property 
 and prevents his making the payment to B. 'The legatee cannot 
 plead that as against the heir the condition is fulfilled, for the 
 heir is merely doing what he is by law entitled to do. The heir 
 does not execute the seizure in order to prevent the fulfilment of the 
 condition, but in order to enforce in a lawful manner the payment 
 of what is due to him. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 212. : 
 
 If the interpretation of the contract is doubtful the presump- 
 tion is against the debtor being free to prevent the performance 
 of the condition. (O. A. Alex. 22 fevr. 1900, B.L.J. XII, 126.) 
 
 There are many illustrations of the rule that if the conditional 
 debtor wrongfully prevents the fulfilment of the condition i!t is 
 treated in a question with him as having been fulfilled. Thus^ 
 where the creditor holds a promissory note, and, as security for 
 the payment of the note, property is pledged to him which he is 
 to return if he collects the amount of the note, then, if it is by 
 his own fault or negligence that he fails to collect the money he 
 must return the property pledged. His fault might be, for ex- 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 343 
 
 ample, thai he had released one of the parties to the note and that 
 the other parties were insolvent. 
 
 In a French case where certain payments for work done were 
 to be paid only after the work had been approved of, and after 
 examination of certain statements by an official, and it was held 
 proved that the party conditionally liable had maliciously pre- 
 vented the necessary statements from being laid before this official, 
 it was held that the condition must be taken as fulfilled. (Cass. 
 2 avril 1873, D. 73. 1. 374.) 
 
 And when a price had to be fixed by two experts, and one of the 
 parties induced an expert to refuse to act, it was held that the court 
 might appoint another expert in his place. (See Larombiere, on 
 art. 1178, n. 11.) And when a man bound himself to pay a 
 certain sum after he had sold an immoveable, and he arbitrarily 
 refused reasonable offers to Jbuy the immoveable, it was held that 
 the condition must be considered as fulfilled. Chambery, 13 
 dec. 1897, D. 1900. 2. 213.) 
 
 The converse of C. C. F. 1178 is also true. If the party in 
 whose interest it is that a condition should be fulfilled, wrongfully 
 procures its fulfilment he cannot take the advantage. For 
 example, if you promise me L.E. 100 if you sell goods of any 
 manufaeture except mine, and I fraudulently mingle goods made 
 by others with your stock, so that you. sell them inadvertently, I 
 cannot claim the penalty. Similarly, if one person is to receive an 
 advantage, such as a legacy, or the sum in an insurance policy oil 
 the death of another and he brings about the death, he cannot take 
 the benefit. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 808; Larombiere, on 
 art. 1178, n. 1; Poitiers, ler fevr. 1881, S. 82. 2. 27, Journal du 
 Palais, 82, p. 201.) 
 
 Comparison with other laws. 
 
 This is one of those general rules of law which are recognised 
 under many systems. 
 
 The German Code, the Swiss Code of Obligations and .the 
 Morocco Code of Obligations all contain similar articles to 
 C. C. F. 1178. The German Code says: — 
 
 Lorsque hi realisation de la condition, contre toute loyaute et 
 canfiance reciproque, est empeehee par la partie au detriment d< 
 laquelle elle eut tourne, la condition vaut comme redlisee. Lors- 
 que la realisation de la condition, contre toute loyaute et von fiance 
 reciproque, est produitc par la partie a Vacant cup de laquelle ill, 
 
344 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 doit tourner, cette realisation vaut comme ?ion avenue. (C. C. 
 Allemand, art. 162.) 
 
 The Swiss Code says: — 
 
 La condition est reputee accompiie quand Vane des parties en 
 a empeche Vevenement au mepris des regies de la bonne foi. 
 (Code des Obligations, art. 156.) 
 
 And the Morocco Code says: — 
 
 La condition est reputee accompiie, lorsque le debiteur, oblige 
 sous condition, en a sans droit empeche Vevenement ou est en 
 demeure de Vaccomplir. La condition accompiie ne produit aucun 
 effet, lorsque Vevenement a eu lieu par le dol de celui qui etait 
 inter esse a ce que la condition s'accomplit. (Code Marocain, 
 arts. 122, 123.) 
 
 And in the English law, too, if a party prevents the performance 
 of the condition its performance is dispensed with. 
 
 In a Scotch case in the House of Lords the principle was applied 
 in a contract of sale where payment of the price was conditional 
 on a certain thing being dona by the seller, land the buyer prevented 
 the possibility of the seller fulfilling the condition. Lord Black- 
 burn said: " I think I may safely say as a general rule that where 
 in a written contract it appears that both parties are agreed that 
 something shall be done which cannot effectually be done unless 
 both concur in doing it, the construction of the contract is that 
 each agrees to do all that is necessary to be done on his part for 
 the carrying out of that thing, though there may be no express 
 words to that effect." (Mackay v. Dick, 1881, 6 A. C. 251, 263. 
 Cf. Re Coleman's Dep. and Life and Health Assoc, 1907, 2 
 K. B. 798, 78 L. J. K. B. 865; Leake, Contracts, 6th ed. 
 p. 479.) 
 
 In Mackai/s case the buyer had bought a machine subject to 
 the condition that the seller should show that it could satisfy a 
 certain test. The buyer refused to give the seller an opportunity 
 of making the test, and it was held that he must pay for the 
 machine as if the condition had been fulfilled. 
 
 Another English case also illustrates this rule. The plaintiff, 
 a broker, was retained by the directors of a company to dispose 
 of the shares. He was to receive £100 clown and £400 
 more when all the shares had been allotted. By the act of the 
 directors, without any default on the part of the plaintiff, the 
 company was wound up before all the shares had been disposed 
 of. It was hold that the plaintiff was entitled to damages. (Inch- 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 345 
 
 bald v. Western Neilgherry Coffee Co., 1864, 17 C. B. N. S. 
 733, 142 R. R. 603. See supra, I, p. 359.) 
 
 These rules are illustrations of the general principle that a man 
 cannot take advantage of his own fault or fraud. 
 
 The effects of the failure of the condition. 
 
 In the case of the suspensive condition the effects of failure 
 are easily stated. The contract becomes an absolute nullity and 
 can produce no effects. As the old brocard expresses it, actus 
 conditionalis dejecta conditione nihil est. That which has been 
 promised conditionally cannot be claimed. (Rouen, 3 janv. 1906, 
 D. 1906. 2. 242.) 
 
 If anything has been paid or delivered it must be restored. 
 (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. Ill; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 2, n. 
 849.) In the case of the failure of a resolutive condition, the risk 
 which hung over the contract has now vanished. The contract now 
 becomes irrevocable and unconditional. For instance, I sell you 
 my house, but stipulate a right of redemption at any time within 
 two years. I allow the two years to expire without exercising 1 
 my right of redemption. You are absolute owner as from the 
 date of the sale. If you have created any real rights such as 
 hypothecs over the house they stand good. If I have affected 
 to create any such rights they now fall to the ground. They never 
 had more than a contingent existence, and now that the right of 
 redemption upon the exercise of which they depended is at an 
 end they can never become effectual. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 123; C. A. Alex. 4 dec. 1901, B. L. J. XIV, 31.) 
 
 The effects of fulfilment of the condition. 
 
 The broad principle is stated in the Egyptian Code thus: 
 When the condition, is fulfilled, the obligation and the rights 
 which floiv from it shall be deemed to have been existent or void 
 from the moment when the event was made a condition of the 
 obligation. (C. C. E. 105/159.) Nevertheless, if perform- 
 ance has become impossible before the event, which was to bring 
 the obligation into existence, has taken place, such event shall 
 have no effect. (C. C. E. 106/160.) The French Code says : 
 The fulfilment of the condition has a retroactive effect to the 
 day on which the obligation was contracted. If the creditor be 
 
346 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 dead before the fulfilment of the condition his rights pass to his 
 
 heir*. .< . ('. F. 1171). Cf. C. C. Q. 1085.) 
 
 When the condition is fulfilled it becomes clear that the condi- 
 tional right which passed to the heirs or representatives had a 
 substantial value. It is regarded as having been a present asset 
 at the date of the contract. Thus, if the conditional creditor 
 married pending the condition, and in the marriage-contract he 
 excluded from the community tons ses biens presents, this ex- 
 pression will include the property of which he was conditional 
 creditor, provided that the condition is fulfilled during the mar- 
 riage. (Larombiere, on art. 1181, n. 19.) 
 
 All alienations, hypothecs or dispositions of any kind made by 
 the conditional debtor fly off. They are all subject to the condi- 
 tion which goes to the root of his right. Similarl}-, such rights 
 created by the conditional creditor during the same period now 
 take effect as if he had been owner at the date of the grant. As 
 regards real rights, in questions with third parties, this state- 
 ment is subject to the rules as to registration; third parties in 
 good faith and for value whose rights have been registered being 
 entitled to rely on the register and to plead that rights unregis- 
 tered shall not affect them, and purchasers of moveables being 
 entitled to rely on the protection given them by the application of 
 the rule possession vaut litre. (C. C. E. 611/737, 615. 742, 
 617/744, 608/734.) The retroactive effect which the law gives 
 to the fulfilment of this condition may be illustrated by the 
 following Quebec cases. If a contract is made for a term of five 
 years with an option in favour of one of the parties to renew it 
 for a further term of five years, the option has the effect of a 
 suspensive condition as regards the second term of five years. 
 And if the option is exercised, the effect is the same as if the 
 contract had been made at the outset for ten years. So a party 
 who agreed to make certain payments till the expiration of the 
 contract is bound to do so for the whole period. (Wolf v. Brook, 
 1908, R. J. Q. 18 K. B. 17.^ A commercial traveller made a 
 sale of fungibles on condition that his employer signified his 
 approval. The employer wrote signifying approval. The effect 
 is that the contract is made at the place where the traveller made 
 it. The condition retroaets, and the contract becomes pure and 
 simple as from its date. (Gault v. Bertrand, 25 Lower Canada 
 Jurist, 340; Mignault, Droit Civil Canadien, 5, p. 444.) 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. 347 
 
 Discussion as to retroactivity. 
 
 In recent years a long- controversy has taken place, originated 
 by Windscheid, as to whether the principle of retroactivity is 
 fairly to be deduced from the texts of the Roman law or can be 
 supported upon logical grounds. Both propositions are denied by 
 Windscheid and by writers who have followed him. (Pandekten, 
 8th ed. 1, s. 91; Ginard, Manuel de Droit Romain, 5th ed. 
 p. 477.) 
 
 It is pointed out that in the French Code, and the same is true 
 of the Egyptian Code, the principle of retroactivity is not carried 
 to its logical conclusion; for, if it were, a sale would not be 
 invalidated by the destruction of the object pending the condition, 
 when this happened without the fault of the debtor. If the object 
 was in existence at the date of the contract that would be sufficient. 
 But the contrary is stated by the code. (C. C. E. 106/160; 
 C. C. F. 1182.) It is also argued that the results attributed to 
 the principle of retroactivity might just as well be assigned to 
 the familiar principle nemo plus juris transferre potest quam ipse 
 haberet. (Dig. 50. 17. 54.) 
 
 The grants made by the conditional debtor or the conditional 
 creditor are necessarily qualified by the condition which affects 
 his right. (See Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 2, n. 809; Rev. Trim. 
 1907, p. 753, art. by M. A. Leloutre; Colin et Capitant, 2, 
 p. 184.) 
 
 But the question whether retroactivity is the best explanation 
 of the effect of fulfilment of the condition is for us not very 
 material, seeing that the codes expressly accept this theory. 
 (C. C. F. 1179; C. C. E. 105/159.) In these articles the codi- 
 fiers follow Pothier, their habitual guide on this subject. (Oblig. 
 n. 220.) There are some cases in which a special provision pre- 
 vents the principle from being applied. For instance, if an owner 
 sells his property subject to a condition, and, pending the condi- 
 tion, he remains in possession of it, and afterwards grants a lease. 
 and, thereafter, the condition is fulfilled does the lease at once 
 fall to the ground? The sound view seems to be that as the seller 
 remained in possession, the intention of the parties was that he 
 should have the powers of administration. Leases, like other' 
 acts of administration, will stand good if there was good faith. 
 (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. Ill; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 823.) 
 This argument receives strong support from the special provision 
 as to the effect of the exercise of a right of redemption. In the 
 
348 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 French Cade where a seller who has a right of redemption exercises 
 the right he is bound to respect leases which have been made 
 without fraud by the buyer. (C. C. F. 1673.) And the Egyptian 
 Code contains a similar provision as to leases not exceeding three 
 years. (C. C. E. 345/431.) 
 
 There is another controversy as to whether when the condition 
 is fulfilled the party who has, pending the condition, been in pos- 
 session must restore the fruits. 
 
 It seems plain that we cannot resolve the question by saying 
 that he should be regarded as a possessor in good faith. 
 
 A possessor in good faith is always a person who is under a 
 mistake as to his true position, whereas here the holder knows the 
 nature of his right. But does it follow, therefore, that the prin- 
 ciple of retroactivity laid down in the code must be carried out 
 and the fruits restored? The question is almost academic, because 
 in most cases the title will indicate the intention of the parties. 
 When there is no such indication it is difficult to avoid applying 
 the principle of retroactivity. (In this sense, Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 116; Hue, 7, n. 277.) The Egyptian Code seems to 
 make this principle govern the whole matter of conditional obli- 
 gations. Under the French Code it is possible to argue from the 
 analogy of other articles that the rule of retroactivity does not 
 apply to this case. (In this sense, B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 824;' 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 186; Chambery, 28 mars 1899, D. 1901. 
 2. 300; Cass. 13 mai 1873, D. 73. 1. 417; D. N. C. C. art. 1183, 
 n. 83.) It is noteworthy that the German and the Swiss codes 
 have rejected the fiction of retroactivity. (German Code, art. 
 158; Cosack, Lehrbuch, 1, p. 226; Code Fed. Oblig. arts. 151- 
 154.) 
 
 The risk. 
 
 The subject of the risk is treated in the French Code as follows: 
 When the obligation has been contracted under a suspensive 
 condition the thing which forms the object of the agreement 
 remains at the risk of the debtor who has bound himself to deliver 
 the thing only upon the fulfilment of the condition. If. without 
 the fault of the debtor, the thing have altogether perished, the 
 obligation is extinguished. If the thing be deteriorated without 
 the fault of the debtor, the creditor has the choice either of dis- 
 solving the obligation, or of receiving the thing in the state in 
 which it is, without diminution of price. If the thing be deterio- 
 rated by the fault of the debtor, the creditor mem cither dissolve 
 
CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. ;j49' 
 
 the obligation or exact the thing in the state in which it is, with 
 damages. (C. C. P. 1182.) When the condition is a resolu- 
 tive one the risk is on the person who owes the thing subject to 
 the condition. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, nos. 882, 892; Demolombo, 
 25, n. 463; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 122.) 
 There are three points to be noted: — 
 
 (1) The loss or deterioration must be pendente emiditione. For 
 if the condition has been fulfilled, the obligation has ceased to be 
 conditional and has become pure and simple. 
 
 (2) The kind of obligation contemplated is a synallagmatic 
 one. In the case of a unilateral obligation the loss always falls 
 on the creditor unless there is a special stipulation to the contrary. 
 If I promise to give you something subject to a condition, and 
 the condition fails, the loss is entirely yours, unless there is some 
 special stipulation to the contrary. (Larombiere, on art. 1182,, 
 n. 3.) 
 
 (3) If the thing has altogether perished there is no obligation. 
 The French article says if the thing has entirely perished without 
 the fault of the debtor V obligation est eteinte. This is ambiguous 
 because it might mean that though the debtor's obligation was 
 extinguished, and he was no longer bound to deliver the thing, 
 the obligation of the creditor to make the payment on his side 
 was still subsisting. 
 
 The prevailing view in France is, however, in favour of the 
 sense that if the thing perishes without fault pending the condition 
 both parties are free. This was the Roman law and it was followed 
 by Pothier. (D. 18. 6. 8; Pothier, Oblig. n. 219; Pand. Franc. 
 Oblig. n. 829; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 853 a; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 111.) 
 
 And the Egyptian Code seems to adopt this theory and to 
 apply it even in the case of sale, difficult as it is to reconcile 
 the articles on the subject. (C. C. E. 266/336, 297/371; infra, 
 pp. 476 seq.) 
 
350 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XVIII. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. 
 
 An obligation with a term is one in which the debtor binds him- 
 self to pay or to perform something at a future date. The future 
 date may be one which is fixed beforehand, as in the case of a 
 bill of exchange payable three months after date, or it may be 
 one which cannot be determined as yet, as when the debtor binds 
 himself to make a payment on the death of a person living. 
 But, in either case, the term is a period which is certain to arrive, 
 though the time of its arrival may be as yet uncertain. There 
 is not consequently, in this case, as in the case of the conditional 
 obligation, a doubt as to whether the debtor will ever be bound to 
 fulfil what he has promised. He is bound from the beginning, 
 though the time of payment is postponed. In some cases the term 
 is indefinite, as, for example, " to pay when my means permit," 
 and in such cases the French courts do not hesitate to fix a term 
 for the payment if satisfied of the debtor's ability to pay. (Paris, 
 19 nov. 1912, D. 1913. 2. 126.) The French Code gives a defini- 
 tion of a term which the Egyptian Code omits: A teim differs 
 from a (suspensive) condition inasmuch as it does not suspend 
 the obligation, but only delays the execution of it. (C. C. F. 
 1185.) The old maxim qui a terme ne doit rien is not literally 
 true; it means only that the debtor is not obliged to pay at present. 
 A term may be created by law, or by a judgment, as when] thef 
 defendant is ordered to make execution within a certain delay, 
 or b} r the agreement of parties. When a delay is fixed by a judg- 
 ment it is called by French writers terme de grace or delai de 
 grace. (See C. C. E. 168/231, 333/415; C. C. F. 1244; Planiol, 
 2, n. 369.) When the term is conventional it is frequently im- 
 plied. When the performance of the obligation by the debtor 
 necessarily requires some delay, and no time is fixed by the parties 
 for fulfilment, a reasonable delay is implied. And, on the other 
 hand, there are cases in which, though no term has been fixed by 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. 351 
 
 the parties, the court can infer from the nature of the contract and 
 from the circumstances, that the performance was intended to be 
 made within a certain delay. (Sec supra, I, p. -364.) Pend- 
 ing the arrival of the term the creditor cannot sue for the debt, 
 but he would, no doubt, be entitled to do conservatory acts if he 
 could show that his interests were imperilled. For even a condi- 
 tional creditor has this right, and a fortiori, the creditor whose 
 debtor has the benefit of a term. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 993; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 148. 
 
 It would appear, however, that the creditor whose right is 
 subject to a term is not entitled to bring an action in the name 
 of his debtor. This is more than a conservatory act, it is an act 
 of execution. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Obliff. 1, n. 629; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 200; supra, p. 97.) And a creditor 
 in a debt subject to a term who is sued by his debtor upon another 
 debt which is due cannot plead compensation, because compensa- 
 tion requires that both debts shall be due. (C. C. E. 194/258; 
 C. C. F. 1291.) 
 
 Repetition of debt paid before the term arrives. 
 
 If the debtor pays the debt subject to the term before the time 
 of payment arrives can he bring the action of repetition? The 
 French Code has an article .which expressly answers this question 
 in the negative: ce qui n'est du qiCa tefrrte, ne pent etre exige 
 avant Vecheance du terime ; mais ce qui a ete paye d'avanoe, ne 
 peut etre repete (art. 1186). 
 
 The article, it is to be observed, does not say anything about 
 error. It states a rule in terms which are quite general. But 
 there are two cases to be considered: 
 
 (1) The debtor knows the debt is not yet due, but he chooses 
 to pay it. 
 
 (2) The debtor thinks that the debt is due and pays it under 
 that belief, whereas in reality it is not due. 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no corresponding article, and the 
 question must therefore be answered jn the Egyptian law by 
 consideration of general principles. There is no difficulty about 
 the case where the debtor voluntarily pays before the term. If 
 he, knowing that ho is entitled to a delay, chooses to pay the debt 
 at once, this is a clear indication that he waives his claim to insist 
 upon the delay. It is true that the law does not presume that a 
 man renounces any of his rights, but, on the other hand, it does 
 
352 THE LAW OF OHLIGATIONS. 
 
 not lay down any general requirements of form for a renunciation.. 
 A renunciation may be tacit as well as express, and here we have 
 a tacit renunciation which appears merely from the conduct of 
 the debtor. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 988; Aubry et Eau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 135, note 10; D. N. C. C. art. 1186, n. 37.) 
 
 But what are we to say of the case when the debtor pays his 
 debt before it is due under the mistaken impression that it is due? 
 There can be no doubt that if this mistake is brought about by 
 the fraud of the other party the debtor can repeat what he has 
 paid. (Demolombe, 25, n. 368.) 
 
 But apart from this case, does the error of the debtor entitle 
 him to repetition? In France the prevailing opinion is against 
 his having such a right. The argument is that article 1186 is 
 expressed in unqualified terms making no distinction between a 
 payment in the knowledge of the term, and a payment in error, 
 and that we are not entitled to introduce a modification of the 
 plain words of the code. (Larombiere, on art. 1186, n. 34 ;. 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 988; Aubry et Eau, I.e.; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1186, n. 41.) 
 
 Some French writers make a distinction. They say that art. 
 1186 forbids the repetition of the capital sum of the debt; it 
 does not say anything with regard to the interest. If the debtor 
 pays his debt before it is due the creditor who gets the use of the 
 money so much earlier is enriched without a cause, and the debtor 
 would be entitled to repeat the amount of this enrichment, 
 although the code forbids his repeating the debt itself. (Demo- 
 lombe, 25, n. 637.) But most French authorities rightly reject 
 this distinction. The language of art. 1186 is absolute, and if 
 the legislator had intended the inter murium to be recovered he 
 would have said so. 
 
 Moreover, the practical difficulties, if the other intei-pretation 
 be adopted, are very serious. How are we to reckon the advantage 
 that the creditor has received? He may not have invested the 
 money at all, or, if it was not money but a corps certain which 
 he had received he may have destroyed it, or have made no use of 
 it. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 989; Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 135, note 10.) But these difficulties, perhaps, do not need to 
 trouble us, because the Egyptian Code contains no article corre- 
 sponding to art. 1186. Under the Egyptian law it seems that re- 
 petition of the capital should be allowed. The debtor has simply 
 paid in error what was not due, and according to the general rule 
 the creditor is bound to return it. (C. C. E. 145/206.) 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. .353 
 
 Presumption that term is in favour of the debtor. 
 
 It is only when the term is in favour of the debtor that lie is 
 allowed to pay the debt before it is due without the consent of the 
 creditor. But the presumption is thai the term is in favour of 
 the debtor. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: When an obligation is subject to 
 a term, the debtor may 'perform the obligation before such term 
 has arrived, provided such performance is not inconsistent with 
 the purpose of the obligation. (C. C. E. 101/155.) The French 
 Code says, more simply: Le terme est toujours presume stipule 
 cu faveur du debiteur, a mains qu'il ne result e de la stipulation, 
 on des cir Constances, qu'il a ete aussi convenu en favtur du 
 creancier. (C. C. F. 1187.) The practical importance of de- 
 ciding whether the term is in favour of the debtor only, is that 
 if this is the case he is free to renounce the term and to make 
 the performance at once. 
 
 For example, where no interest is stipulated for in a contract 
 of loan of money, the presumption is that the term is fixed solely 
 in favour of the debtor. And, in a voluntary deposit, although 
 it may have been agreed that the depositary should take care of 
 the thing for three months, the depositor can demand it back at 
 any time, because the depositary has no interest to refuse this, 
 and the delay fixed was solely for the benefit of the depositor. 
 (C. C. F. 1944; C. C. Q. 1810. Cf. C. C. E. 482/590. 
 
 But the terms of the contract, or the circumstances, may dis- 
 place the presumption that the term is solely in favour of the 
 debtor, and show that the term was in favour of the creditor also. 
 (C. C. E. 101/155; C. C. F. 1187; C. C. Q. 1091.) 
 
 Thus, in the case of a loan of money on interest, or of a deposit 
 of money with a bank, which, although it is called deposit, is 
 really a loan of money on interest, the term is very often for the 
 benefit of both parties. (Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barcle, Oblig. 
 2, n. 980; Aubry et Ran, 5th eel. 4, p. 142, note 21; Planiol, 2, 
 n. 2215.) And in the Egyptian law the presumption will be 
 that this was so, for we have not any article creating an adverse 
 presumption. 
 
 But it is a mere presumption of fact. It is a question of the 
 interpretation of the particular contract. 
 
 It may appear that the loan was not a business transaction, 
 but was an office of friendship, although interest was to be paid. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, op. cit . n. 981. See Cass. 21 avril 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 23 
 
;j;->4 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 L896, D. 96. 1. 484; note by M. Planiol to Trib. fed. Suisse, 
 ler mars 1890, D. 92. 2. 169; C. A. Alex. 24 dec. 1890, B.L.J. 
 Ill, 90; C. A. Alex. 2 mai 1895, B. L. J. VII, 245.) Although, 
 as a general rule, a creditor is not bound to take payment before 
 the term, yet when such payment is offered a few days before 
 the mat tiling of the obligation, and he refuses to accept it without 
 having any real interest to do so, the court may find that the 
 creditor is in bad faith in refusing payment, and that there has 
 been a valid tender. 
 
 Computation of the term. 
 
 In computing a term the dies ad quem is included, and the 
 dies a quo is not included. Thus, if the debtor has bound himself 
 to pay on the first of May he cannot be sued till the second of 
 May, because the whole of May 1st is included in the delay. 
 (Larombiere on art. 1186, n. 17; Pand. Franc. Oblig. n. 1379; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1003; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 136, 
 note 11.) And when the debtor has bound himself on the 1st of 
 March to pay in ten days, the 1st of March is not reckoned, and 
 the obligation is not due till March 11th, and, seeing that the 
 debtor will not be in delay if he pay on the last moment of 
 March 11th, the action cannot be brought against him till March 
 12th. 
 
 When the delay J or an appeal is fixed bylaw and it expires on 
 a legal holiday the delay is extended to the day following. (C. A. 
 Alex. 14 avr. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 319.) 
 
 The risk during the term. 
 
 II the debtor has bound himself to deliver a specific thing after 
 lain delay, and it lias perished without his fault before the 
 arrival of the term, he is liberated from his obligation to deliver 
 it. But is the other party liberated also? In the case of sale it is a 
 settled principle of the French law that the buyer must still pay 
 the price, though the seller from no fault of his own cannot deli's i ■;• 
 that which he has undertaken to do. (Pothier, Vente, n. 307; 
 Hue, 7, n. 105; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 128.) 
 
 This, however, may be explained as an application of the prin- 
 ciple res perit domino. But suppose it has been stipulated that 
 the buyer shall not become owner until delivery, or that, in spite 
 of the delivery, the buyer shall not become owner until the price 
 has been paid, doe- this not affect the liability of the buyer to pay 
 the price? 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. 355 
 
 We cannot say here that he must, do so upon the ground that 
 -when the thing was lost he was its owner. This is in the French 
 laAv a disputed question. The French Code says: "The obliga- 
 tion to deliver a thing is completed by the mere consent of the 
 parties. 
 
 " It makes the creditor owner and puts the thing at his risk 
 from the time that it ought to have been delivered." 'C. C. F. 
 1138.) 
 
 This lends considerable force to the argument that the risk is 
 on the creditor only when he has become owner of the thing, and 
 this A r iew is supported by some considerable authorities, and 
 appears to be sound. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. l,n. 424; 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 1"29. Contra, Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 58, 
 bis ill. 
 
 In the Egyptian law there is no doubt. If, in spite of the 
 transfer of ownership, the risk is on the seller until delivery, this 
 will be so a fortiori when the obligation to deliver lies upon a 
 debtor who remains the owner of the thing. C. C. E. 297/371.) 
 
 And in the Egyptian law both parties will be liberated by the 
 destruction of the thing without fault of the party whose duty it 
 was to deliver it. C. C. E. 170 /242." 
 
 Loss of right to claim the term. 
 
 An obligation, subject to a term becomes performable imme- 
 diately if the debtor becomes bankrupt, or if lie has by his own 
 conduct impaired the securities for performance. (C. C. E. 
 102 156; C. C. F. 1188; C. C.Q. 1092.) 
 
 There is what the French writers call a deehcance du terme. 
 
 There are two reasons commonly given for this rule as to the 
 effect of bankruptcy upon a debt subject to a term: — 
 
 1 Tin creditor gave the debtor a delay because he had con- 
 fidence in him. The basis of this confidence is destroyed if the 
 debtor becomes bankrupt. 
 
 (2) If such debts were not made exigible by bankruptcy great 
 complications would ensue. It would be impossible to divide 
 the estate of the bankrupt, because provision would need to be 
 made for these claims not yet due, and sums would have to be set 
 aside to meet them. B.-L. et Bardte, Oblig. 2, n. 1007; Aubry 
 et Kan, 5th ed. 4, p. 136.) 
 
 23 (2) 
 
356 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Does the insolvency of a non-trader produce the same effect 
 as the bankruptcy of a trader? 
 
 In France it is universally agreed that it does. The term 
 "bankruptcy" — faillite — in this article is used in a broad 
 sense. The Code of Quebec,, with greater precision, says the 
 debtor cannot claim the benefit of the term " when he has become a 
 bankrupt or insolvent." (C. C. Q. 1092.) In its strict sense, 
 " bankruptcy " belongs only to the commercial law and is dealt 
 with in the Commercial Code. 
 
 The Egyptian Commercial Code, like the French, says: Lc 
 jugement declaratif de la faillite rend exigibles a Vegard dn failli 
 les dettes non echues. (C. Com. E. 221/229; C. Com. F. 444.) 
 
 It is universally agreed that the word faillite in article 1188 of 
 the French Civil Code includes the deconfiture of a non-trader. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1012; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 137, 
 note 12; Cass. 12 dec. 1899, D. 1900. 1. 112; Bo urges, 10 mai 
 1892, D. 92. 2. 445; D. N. C. C. art. 1188, n. 24.) 
 
 It appears from the Travaux preparatoires that the suggestion 
 to leave out of the French Civil Code the reference to faillite and. 
 to refer for that subject to the Commercial Code was met by the 
 answer that on peat faillir sans etre marchand : a la verite, la 
 faillite alors est appelee deconfiture ; mai* peu importe-la de- 
 nomination lorsque la chose est la meme. (Locre. XII, p. 162, 
 n. 11.) 
 
 This shows that faillite is bene used in a broad sense. And 
 in the old French law also the deconfiture of a non-trader mad" 
 his debts at once exigible. ( Bo urj on. Droit Commun de la France, 
 liv. VI, tit. VIII, n. 34.) 
 
 The conclusion that in the Egyptian law " bankruptcy " here 
 includes the insolvency of a non-trader is made almost certain by 
 a comparison of article 102 156 of the Egj ptian Civil Codes with 
 art. 281 '353. The latter article gives the unpaid vendor the 
 right to retain the thing sold and not delivered, if the purchaser has 
 diminished the security accorded by him for the payment of the 
 \ or if he is dans un etat de deconfiture, or, as it is in the 
 English version, " in a state of insolvency which renders imminent 
 the loss of the price to the vendor." And the vendor is to have this 
 right of retention even if the term agreed upon for payment has 
 not arrived, unless security is given him. This is simply a special 
 application of the general principle laid down in C. ( . E. 102 '156,. 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. 357 
 
 and, ii! a state of insolvency is enough in the one case, it must be 
 enough in the other. 
 
 And in the English version of the Mixed Commercial Code the 
 word "insolvency" is used instead of "bankruptcy." Chap. 
 III.) 
 
 The commercial codes contain another illustration of the rule 
 that bankruptcy creates a forfeiture of the term. "Where the 
 maker of a promissory note, the acceptor of a bill of exchange or 
 the drawer of a bill of exchange not accepted, becomes bankrupt, 
 the other parties liable shall be bound to give security for pay- 
 ment at maturity, unless they prefer to pay at once." (O. Com. E. 
 221/229.) 
 
 There is every reason to think that in the Egyptian law, as in 
 the French, the insolvency of a non-trader makes all his debts 
 exigible. But it must be a genuine insolvency, an etat de decon- 
 fiiure, or, as it is expressed in a case about the vendor's right of 
 retention, line decemfiture etabUe. (O. A. Alex. 9 nov. 1905, 
 E. L. J. XVIII, 10.) 
 
 How is insolvency to be determined? 
 Does it need to be declared by a judgment? 
 
 Where there is bankruptcy in the strict sense of the term there 
 is no difficulty in fixing the date at which it commenced. The 
 trader is a bankrupt from the date of the judgment which de- 
 clares him to be in a condition of insolvency — en etat de fcdMihe. 
 (C. Com. E. 195/202.) 
 
 The insolvency of the trader prior to the judgment has certain 
 legal effects, but he is not a bankrupt until he has been so declared 
 by a competent court. (See Thaller, Traite Elemmtaire de Droit 
 Commercial, 4th ed. nos. 1714, 1715.) 
 
 But the codes do not make any rules for determining from what 
 •date a non-trader is to be reputed insolvent. 
 
 Insolvency is a question of fact. A debtor is insolvent when 
 his assets are not sufficient to meet his apparent liabilities. The 
 fact that, he is in a state of temporary embarrassment and cannot 
 meet a particular payment does not necessarily prove that he is 
 insolvent. And the law does not attempt to give any precise 
 definition of insolvency or decon fit lire. (Demolombe, 25, n. 666; 
 Hue, 7, n. 287; Thaller, Traite EUmentaire de Droit Commercial', 
 4th 'ed, n. 1709.) 
 
 Who is then to decide when the debtor is in this condition? 
 
358 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Must there be a judgment which says that at a certain date the 
 debtor was insolvent? The decision of this question has great 
 practical importance in consequence of the rules of compensation. 
 The point may be made clear by illustration. A owes to B 
 L. E. 1,000. for which he has given him a hill at three months. B 
 buys goods from A to the value of L. E. 1,000. If B has reason 
 to doubt A's solvency, can he say " you are insolvent, and there- 
 fore the bill due according to its terms at three months hence has 
 become payable at once. It is a liquid and exigible debt, equal in 
 amount to the debt which I owe to you for the goods, and the two 
 debts are, therefore, compensated"? If B's argument is sound, 
 and if A is really insolvent, B will get payment of his debt in 
 full, because he has got goods equal to the amount, whereas A's 
 other creditors will have to be content with such a proportional 
 payment of their claims as can be obtained from the realisation of 
 A's assets. On the other hand, if there is no insolvency until a 
 court has declared it, there will not be compensation between the 
 two debts, because B's debt on the bill does not become due until 
 the judgment; and in the mi>antime A's other creditors can execute 
 seizures and take measures to protect themselves. If the insol- 
 vency is merely a matter of fact, then, although it may require to 
 be ascertained by the court, the judgment might find that it 
 existed from some particular date, even prior to the commencement 
 of the action. But the sounder view appears to be that insolvency 
 is a condition which does not exist until it has been judicially 
 declared, and that the judgment which declares it does more than 
 merely find that certain facts exist. The judgment does more than 
 declare: it creates a change in the legal position of the debtor. The 
 court, after appreciation of a combination of various facts, pro- 
 nounces that, in its opinion, the debtor is now in a state of 
 insolvency; the judgment modifies his status. 
 
 According to the jurisprudence of the Court of Cassation, the 
 insolvency cannot at any rate be placed earlier than the date on 
 which legal proceedings were commenced — the date of the demande 
 en justice. (Cass. 6 fevr. 1907, D. 1908. 1. 408; Cass. 30 mars 
 1892, D. 92. 1. 281, S. 92. 1. 481, where see the notes by Planiol 
 and Labbe, respectively.) 
 
 According to most writers, the insolvency cannot commence 
 earlier than the date of the judgment which pronounces it. It 
 was not necessary in the particular cases for the Cour de Cassation 
 to place the date later than the demande en justice, but probably 
 this will be the next step in the jurisprudence, as it appears to be 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A TERM. 359" 
 
 the logical result. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 379, note 16; 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1013; Laurent, 18, n. 414.) 
 
 Diminution of securities by the debtor. 
 
 The second case in which, by the article under consideration, 
 the debtor loses the benefit of the term is if he has by his pwn 
 conduct impaired the securities for performance. (C. C. E. 
 102/156.) 
 
 This means no doubt the same as the French Code, which says 
 the debtor loses the benefit of the term when by his act he, has 
 diminished the securities which he had given by the contract to 
 his creditor. (C. C. F. 1188.) It is only when he is diminish- 
 ing a security specially given that the rule is applicable. 
 
 It does not apply to a debtor who, by his extravagance or 
 otherwise, is diminishing his estate which forms the general pledge 
 for the security of all his creditors. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1015: Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 138, note 14; Bourges, 10 
 mai 1892, D. 92. 2. 455; D. N. C. C. art. 1188, n. 55.) 
 
 What amounts to diminishing the security is of course a ques- 
 tion of fact. If a debtor who has given a hypothec over his house 
 pulls the house down, or if a debtor cuts down a wood on a pro- 
 perty which is hypothecated by him, there can be no doubt that the 
 security is impaired. If the debtor alienates an immoveable which 
 is hypothecated, is this an impairment? This is a very disputed 
 question. If it were not for the rules of the purge the alienation 
 would not seem to affect the creditor. The immoveable is still 
 liable for the debt in the hands of its new owner. And when the 
 alienation is a total alienation it does not seem that the creditor 
 suffers any loss. But a partial alienation may, owing to the 
 •purge, be prejudicial to him, as he would have to look to several 
 debtors for payment instead of to one. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 
 1023; Demolombe, 25, n. 686; D. N. O. O. art. 1188, n. 102. 
 See C. A. Alex. 18 dec. 1890, B. L. J. Ill, 80, note.) 
 
 The diminution of the security must be by the debtor's own 
 act; he is not responsible for the diminution caused by a fortuitous 
 event, or by the crime or fault of a third party for whom he is not 
 responsible. B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1025; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 137, note 13; D. N. 0. C. art. 1188, no. 78.) 
 
 • But one important case is dealt with elsewhere in the code. If 
 an immoveable charged with a hypothec perishes or deteriorates 
 by fortuitous event in such a way as to render the security doubtful 
 
360 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the debtor must, at his option, either offer a sufficient hypothec 
 upon another immoveable or pay the debt before it falls due. 
 (C. C. E. 562/686; C. C. F. 2131; C. A. Alex. 17 nov. 1898, 
 B. L. J. XI, 17; Aubry et Rau, he. cit. and 3, p. 710.) 
 
 This provision applies only to the case where there has been a 
 material degradation of the particular immoveable. 
 
 It does not apply to a loss of value due to economic causes. 
 (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 3, p. 711; B.-L. et de Loynes, Privileges 
 et Hypotheques, 2, n. 1392. Contra, Guillouard, Privileges et 
 Hypotheques, 3, n. 1618.) 
 
 Another article of the code provides that a general obligation 
 to furnish a surety, whether contractual or judicial, involves the 
 obligation to procure a new surety, if the first becomes insolvent. 
 (C. C. E. 500/610; C. C. F. 2020.) 
 
 It would appear that the principle laid down in these articles is 
 a general one, and that whenever there has been an impairment 
 of securities brought about, not by the act of the debtor, but by a 
 fortuitous event, the creditor can call upon the debtor to pay at 
 once, or to restore the value of the securities. (Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 137, note 13; Laurent, 17, n. 203; D. N. C. C. art. 
 1188, n. 82.) 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 361 
 
 OHAPTEE XIX. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS IN WHICH THERE ARE SEVERAL OBJECTS 
 AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 
 
 Obligations simple and composite. 
 
 Under this head fall to be considered three kinds of obligations, 
 namely:— 
 
 (1) Alternative; (2) Facultative; (3) Obligations with a 
 
 penalty. 
 
 A simple obligation is one in which there is a single debtor 
 and a single creditor, and in which the object of the obligation is 
 a single prestation; for example, I promise to deliver to you my 
 horse. The promise to transfer a group of things regarded col- 
 lectively is, in this sense, a single prestation. If I promise to 
 sell to you my whole stock-in-trade, or my whole crop of cotton, 
 or to pay you a sum of money with interest, this is a simple obliga- 
 tion just as much as if I promised to deliver to you my horse. 
 The various items which compose the stock-in-trade, or the sepa- 
 rate bales of cotton, are not regarded individually, and the obliga- 
 tion to pay the interest upon the capital sum promised is not a 
 separate obligation. The obligation is to pay the capital with the 
 interest as a single sum. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 68.) On 
 the other hand, an obligation is said to be composite when there 
 are several distinct prestations due, that is to say, several different 
 objects. And the composite obligation may be (a) conjunctive, 
 or (b) alternative. If, though there are several objects, I have 
 bound myself to pay them all at once, this is a conjunctive obliga- 
 tion. If I promise to deliver to you my horse and my ox, I enter 
 into two separate and distinct obligations, which are only, so to 
 speak, accidentally combined by being created together and by 
 the same title. 
 
 And if I promise to deliver to you my horse or my ox, seeing 
 that it is at present undetermined upon which the choice shall 
 fall, 1 am bound at first to two prestations, although when the 
 choice is made my obligation will be reduced to a single one. In 
 
,",62 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 this typo of obligation, which is called the alternative obligation, 
 there arc two things due or two objects. C. C. F. 1189.) This 
 will be explained more fully later. In what is called a facultative 
 obligation there is only one thing- due. It is a simple obligation, 
 though its simplicity is disguised. The debtor is bound to one 
 prestation only, but he has the right, if he prefers it, to liberate 
 himself by substituting another prestation. The rather fine dis- 
 tinction between the facultative and the alternative obligation will 
 be dealt with later on. 
 
 Obligations simple and multiple. 
 
 When, instead of there being a single creditor and a single 
 debtor, the obligation is in favour of several creditors, or is due 
 by several debtors, the obligation is conveniently called a multiple 
 obligation to distinguish it from a simple obligation. Instead 
 of the obligation having a. plurality of objects it has a plurality; 
 of subjects. The definition of an obligation in the Egyptian 
 Code is somewhat incomplete upon this point. It says the object 
 of an obligation is to procure an advantage for one person by 
 constraining another. The French Code with greater fulness 
 says that in a contract une on plusieurs personnes x'obligent etnvers 
 une ou plusieurs a at res. [C C. E. 90/144; C. C. F. 1101.) 
 
 And this plurality of debtors or of creditors, as the case may 
 be, is not necessarily found at the date of the creation of the obliga- 
 tion. It may arise, and frequently does arise, subsequently, as. 
 for instance, when a creditor or a debtor dies and is succeeded by 
 several heirs. In this way an obligation which was at first simple 
 becomes afterwards multiple. See, on these distinctions gene- 
 rally, Aubry et Ran. 5th ed. 4, p. 16 and p. 68; Planiol, 2, n. 707 
 and 714; Panel. Frcmc. vo. Obligations, n. 127.) 
 
 Alternative obligations. 
 
 An alternative obligation is one in which the debtor is bound 
 to give or to do one of two things. For example, he binds himself 
 to do a piece of work, or otherwise to pay a sum of money. The 
 obligation is to be extinguished in one of these two ways. He 
 must do either the one thing or the other, but he cannot compel 
 the creditor to accept a part of one of these things and a part of the 
 other. Unless the creditor agrees, the debtor cannot say, "I will 
 pay half the money and do half the work/' This rule is expressly 
 stated in the French Code. C. C.F. 1191. Cf . C. C. Q. 1093. 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 363 
 
 The Egyptian law is undoubtedly the same although the code 
 is silent upon this poini . 
 
 Alternative obligation distinguished from conjunctive or 
 facultative obligation. 
 
 The alternative obligation must be distinguished from two other 
 kinds of obligations which bear a resemblance to it, viz., (a) a 
 conjunctive obligation, and (b a facultative obligation. 
 
 (a) A conjunctive obligation is one in which the debtor is 
 bound cumulatively to do two or more things, for instance, to pay 
 a sum of money and to do a piece of work. In this case there are 
 two separate obligations, though they may happen to be created 
 by the same title. One of the obligations may bo extinguished, 
 and the other may remain due. As the old lawyers said, there 
 are two things in obligutione. 
 
 (b) A facultative obligation is one in which the debtor binds 
 himself to do one thing only, but reserves to himself the choice of 
 substituting something else, that is, of liberating himself from his 
 obligation by doing something else than that which he primarily 
 undertook to do. In this kind of obligation there is in principle 
 only one thing due— unum est in obligatione — but when the time 
 of payment arrives the debtor can substitute something else. The 
 distinction between an alternative obligation and a facultative 
 obligation is a somewhat subtle one and will be best considered, 
 after the rules of alternative obligations have been explained. 
 (Infra, p. 378.) 
 
 In an alternative obligation who has the choice? 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: When an obligation is alternative, 
 the option, in the absence of any special provision of the law or pi 
 the agreement, belongs to the debtor. (C. C. E. 96/150.) 
 
 This is in accordance with the French law. (O. O. F. 1190. 
 Cf . O. C. Q. 1094.) It is, in fact, an application of the general 
 rule of interpretation of contracts that in cases of doubt the con- 
 struction shall be in favour of the party who incurs the obligation. 
 (C. C. E. 140/201; C. C. F. 1162; C. C. Q. 1019.) 
 
 It is not. necessary to use a sacramental form of words in order 
 to displace the presumption that the choice is with the debtor, 
 but the intention of the parties must clearly appear from the 
 terms of the agreement, interpreted in the light of the circum- 
 stances, and sometimes by reference to usage. (Aubry et Jtau, 
 
364 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 oth ed. 4, p. 69, note 3 ter; Demolombe, 26, n. 38.) The Egyptian 
 Code gives as an example of an alternative obligation in which the 
 choice is with the creditor, the case of an obligation with a penal 
 clause. If I undertake to do certain work, or to pay a penalty, 
 my creditor can sue me for performance of the work when that is 
 possible instead of suing for the penalty. (C. C. E. 98/152.) 
 
 But the obligation with a penal clause is best considered sepa- 
 rately, as it has peculiarities which do not belong to alternative 
 obligations in general. When the debtor has the option, and the 
 creditor sues for performance, he must sue for either of the two 
 things alternatively; he cannot limit his action to one of them, for, 
 otherwise, he would be exercising the option which belongs to 
 the debtor. Pothier, Oblig. n. 248; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1060.) 
 And when no delay is fixed within which the choice is to be made, 
 the debtor can only be deprived of his option by the expiration of 
 a delay fixed by a judgment against him, or by one of the modes of 
 performance becoming impossible. But when the debtor has a 
 choice of doing one of two things within a certain delay, and, 
 failing his doing one of them within the specified time, he is to be 
 bound to do the other, then, if the delay has expired, the creditor 
 can sue for performance of this other thing. For example, a 
 creditor may agree to take a dividend on condition that the debtor 
 pays instalments on fixed dates, on the terms that if the debtor is 
 in arrears with any instalment the creditor's right to sue for pay- 
 ment of the debt in full shall revive. 
 
 A Quebec case is a good illustration of this rule: It was con- 
 tracted between a newspaper and a trader that the trader should 
 furnish so many lines of advertisement in a year, and in con- 
 sideration of this quantity the rate was to be a specially low one. 
 
 But the contract provided that the advertiser was to pay by the 
 month, and that if each month's payment was not promptly made 
 the rate for the advertisements should no longer be the special 
 rate, but should be the ordinary rate for casual advertisers. 
 
 The trader having failed to pay at the time specified, the creditor 
 sued for payment on the higher scale, and it was held that there was 
 here a valid alternative obligation, and that failure to fulfil the 
 condition entitled the creditor to sue for the remaining alternative. 
 (Berthiaulme v. Kent, 1902, R. J. Q. 11 K. B. 312.) 
 
 Refusal to exercise the option. 
 
 If the debtor by refusing to exercise the choice prevents the ful- 
 filment of the obligation, the creditor can call upon him by an 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 365 
 
 action to make his choice, and failing his doing so, ask that the 
 court shall fix a delay within which he is to exercise the choice or, 
 if not, that the court shall make the choice for him. The same rule 
 applies in the case where the choice is given to a creditor, or when 
 by the death of the party entitled to make the choice the right of 
 making it has passed to several heirs and they cannot agree. 
 (Larombiere, art. 1191, n. 7 and n. 11; Demolombe, 26, nos. 39 
 and 41; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, nos. 1071—1073; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 69.) 
 
 German Code as to this. 
 
 The German Code contains two new rules upon this matter 
 which are worth noting: Si le debiteur, lorsqiiil a le droit d 'op- 
 tion, ne procede pas au choix avant le commencement de la pro- 
 cedure d'executian forcee, le creamier pent, a son choix, faire 
 porter V execution forcee sur Vune ou V autre des prestations; 
 toutefois, aussi longiemps que le creancier n'a pas regu en tout 
 ou en partie la prestation choisie, le debiteur pent se liber er de 
 son engagement en fournissant Vune des autres prestations. Si 
 le creancier, lorsqiiil a le droit d. option, est en demeure, le de- 
 biteur petit, sous condition de lui fixer un delai convenable, Vin- 
 viter a proceder au choix. A V expiration du delai, si le creancier 
 ii a pas procede an choix. en temps utile, le droit d'option passe 
 au debiteur (art. 264, Official French translation. Of . Code 
 Maroc. Oblig. art. 144). 
 
 Can the French or Egyptian courts transfer the choice to the 
 
 other party? 
 
 The rule accepted by the German Code that if the party entitled 
 to make the choice dioes not do so within the delay fixed, the choice 
 passes to the other party is a very reasonable one. And, accord- 
 ing to several of the French authorities, the French courts have 
 the same power, although there is no such provision in the code. 
 But under the French or Egyptian codes it is very doubtful if 
 this is competent. The court has no power to modify the contract 
 of the parties. 
 
 The debtor has bound himself to make one of two prestations 
 in his option. If he will not exercise his option, and specific 
 performance of the contract is demanded, the court cannot give 
 an effective judgment without indicating which of the two pres- 
 tations is to be made. The court must, necessarily, have the 
 
366 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 power of exercising the option between the prestations, but in 
 the silence of the texts the court has no implied authority to 
 delegate this power to the plaintiff. (Sic, Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4. p. 69; Laurent, 17, n. 239; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1071. 
 Contra, Laromhiere, art. 1191, n. 7; Demolombe, 26, n. 39.) 
 
 Transmissibility of the option. 
 
 When the parly entitled to exercise the option dies before the 
 delay has expired during which the option was to be made, the 
 right of making the choice passes to his heirs, being a vested 
 right which is an asset of his estate. The right of making the 
 choice is indivisible by its nature. It is necessary that the heirs 
 should come to an agreement as to the manner in which the option 
 is to be exercised. In a French ease A let a laundry to B upon 
 a lease for a number of years. 
 
 It was stipulated that if B put up additional buildings at the 
 end of the lease, A was to have an option either to take the new 
 buildings at a valuation, or to sell the laundry to B for 1-3,000 
 francs. B erected new buildings, and, after A's death, it was 
 held that his heirs could exercise the option which he enjoyed of 
 taking over the buildings or else of making the lessee buy the 
 property. (Douai, 12 mars 1891, D. 92. 2. 380.; If it is the 
 debtor who has the option and his heirs cannot agree in which 
 way it is to be exercised, their want of agreement cannot inde- 
 finitely paralyse the right of the creditor. 
 
 He can ask the courts to fix a delay within which the heirs 
 must make their option, failing which the court will do so for 
 them. If, on the other hand, it is the heirs of the creditor who 
 cannot agree which of the two things they shall choose, this will 
 he as a rule so much the better for the debtor. He cannot be 
 called upon to pay until the creditors make up their minds. But 
 if he wishes to liberate himself from his obligation he will no 
 doubt have the right to apply to the court to put the creditors in 
 default to make their choice within a certain delay, failing which 
 it is to be made by the judge. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 118, bis, 
 11; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1073. 
 
 How is the option to be declared? 
 
 When the option is with the debtor, can he at any time after 
 the date of the contract declare to the creditor that he proposes to 
 exercise the option in a certain way, and, if he makes such a 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 367 
 
 declaration, does this transform the obligation from an alternative 
 one into a simple one? This is a poinl on which there has been 
 much controversy. If I sell you my black horse or my brown 
 horse at my choice, for a certain price, the option which I reserve 
 of selecting- between the two horses is a clause in my favour. 
 And if I declare to the buyer that I have decided to deliver to 
 him the brown horse has he any legal ground of- complaint? 
 According to the German Code he has not. The party entitled 
 to the option may exercise it by a mere declaration made to the 
 other (art. 263). Some French writers adopt the same view. 
 (Laurent, 17, n. 232; Hue, 7, n. 291.) But this does not appear 
 to be a correct interpretation of the presumed will of the parlies. 
 Although the option belongs to the debtor, the alternative obliga- 
 tion presents distinct advantages to the creditor also. 
 
 It gives him two strings to his bow. If, without the fault of 
 the debtor, one of the modes of performance becomes impossible, 
 the obligation still subsists. To take the illustration just given, 
 if my brown horse is killed by lightning I have no longer an 
 option, I am bound to deliver my black horse. Can the debtor 
 deprive the creditor of this advantage by a mere declaration of 
 will, or do the parties intend that the creditor shall continue to 
 enjoy this additional chance of payment until delivery is made? 
 The latter appears to be the sounder view. The only way in which 
 the debtor can exercise his option is by making an actual delivery 
 of one of the two things, or, if the creditor refuses to take it, by 
 making a tender, that is, by off res reelles. From the creditor's 
 point of view there would be no virtue in the alternative obligation, 
 if the moment after it was made the debtor could turn it into a, 
 simple obligation by informing the creditor that he meant to 
 exercise the choice in a certain way. B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1062; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 70; Colmet de Santerre, 5, 124, 
 bis, 1.) 
 
 When the option was left to the creditor there does not seem 
 any reason against his exercising the choice by a mere declaration 
 of will. If he calls upon the debtor to make one of the prestations 
 this should be sufficient. (Colmet de Santerre, I.e.; B.-L. et 
 Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1067.) If he chooses to deprive himself .of 
 the advantage which the law gives him, and to determine the 
 object of the obligation before the actual delivery, why should he 
 not be allowed to do so? His declaration does not need to be 
 accepted because the debtor has already bound himself to pay- 
 that one of the two things which the creditor should select. Not- 
 
368 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 withstanding this, same French authorities hold that the creditor 
 is not bound by his declaration, unless it is in the form of a 
 demande en justice or has been accepted by the debtor. (Sic. 
 Aubry et Rau, loc. cit.) 
 
 Does the alternative obligation operate an immediate 
 transfer of the property? 
 
 So long as it is still uncertain which of the two prestations will 
 be the object of the obligation there can be no transfer of the 
 ownership. Under the Egyptian Code as under the French law, 
 there can be no transfer of ownership except of a determinate 
 object. (C. C. E. 266, 261/336, 328; Laurent, 17, n. 221.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is clearer upon this point than the French 
 Code. The latter lays down in general terms that the obligation 
 to deliver a thing is perfect by the mere consent of the contracting 
 parties, and that it rend le creancier proprietaire et met la chose 
 a ses risques des V instant ou elle a du etre livree, encore que la 
 tradition n 'en ait point ete faite. (C. C. F. 1138.) 
 
 But this article is only intended to apply to the case when the 
 object of the contract is a corps certain. If the object of the 
 contract, for instance, of a contract of sale, is a quantity of 
 fungibles, the transfer of ownership to the purchaser cannot take 
 place until the fungibles have been sufficiently determined. 
 (Beudant, Contrats, n. 338; Planiol, 2, n. 1343.) And, in the 
 general case, this determination or, as it is often called, this in- 
 dividualisation of the object is made by separating the fungibles 
 sold and delivering them to the purchaser. This subject, how- 
 ever, belongs to the law of sale. (See Thaller, Traite Elementaire 
 de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. n. 1008; B.-L. et Barde, OUig. 
 2, n. 1065.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is quite clear as to this, because it says: 
 In the case of the sale of things determinate only as to ~kind r 
 tht ownership passes only, by delivery. (C. C. E. 268/338.) 
 alternative obligation is strictly analogous to this case. If 
 the debtor binds himself to deliver property X or property Y, as 
 he shall choose, there is no determination of the object, and there- 
 fore no transfer of the property can take place until the choice 
 has been made. 
 
 Retroactive effect of the choice. 
 
 When the choice is made does it retroact to the date of the 
 contract? This is a controversial question. According to one 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 369 
 
 view, seeing that the alternative obligation cannot transfer the 
 ownership, but merely gives to the creditor a personal right, the 
 transmission of property can take place only from the date when 
 the choice is made. (Larombierc, art. 1138, n. 18, and art. 1194, 
 n. 2; Laurent, 17, n. 221.) But, according to another view, when 
 the choice is made it retroacts to the date of the contract. Tho 
 position is the same as if the obligation had not been alternative, 
 but had been from the first a simple obligation to perform the 
 prestation upon which the choice has ultimately rested. It is 
 this view which is accepted by the German Code. La prestation 
 choisie est considered eomme m/fmt ete seule due, des VoHgine 
 (art. 263). Many French authorities hold that the French law 
 is the same, but they do not agree in their explanation of the 
 reason why it should be so. 
 
 According to some of them the alternative obligation conceals 
 a condition. The debtor who promises property X or property Y, 
 in his option, realty promises property X, subject to the condition 
 that he shall choose to deliver that property or else property Y, 
 subject to the same condition. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 115, 
 bis, VI; Demolombc, 26, n. 19.) When the condition is fulfilled 
 it retroacts according to the general rule applicable to conditional 
 obligations. (C. C. F. 1179; C. C. E. 105/159.) 
 
 I am disposed to think that this is still the simplest and best 
 explanation. Some writers, however, consider it too artificial. 
 They say that an alternative obligation and a conditional obliga- 
 tion are two separate things, and Laurent carries the argument to 
 its logical conclusion by holding that, as there is no condition in 
 the alternative obligation^ it is not possible to admit the retro- 
 active effect of the option. (17, n. 221.) 
 
 But other writers who wish to retain the doctrine of retro- 
 activity, and are, at the same time, dissatisfied with the old ex- 
 planation of it, justify their conclusion in another way. 'They 
 say that it is an essential principle of the alternative obligation 
 that when one of the two objects promised alternatively is removed 
 from the scene, either because it becomes impossible to perforin it, 
 or because the choice has fallen upon the other one, the obligation 
 becomes a pure and simple one from its date. There is what has 
 been styled a concentration upon the object which remains. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1078; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 194.) 
 In whatever way the retroactive effect of the choice is to be 
 defended it appears, at any rate, to be the sounder view that the 
 
 w.— vol. ii. 24 
 
370 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 choice does produce a retroactive effect, and this has important 
 pract ical consequences : — 
 
 (1) If the debtor who has sold property X or property Y, in 
 his option, afterwards alienates property X to a third party and 
 then exercises his option under the alternative obligation in 
 favour of X, the creditor can revindicate X from the second pur-r 
 chaser, because it now turns out that he was the owner of it from 
 the date of the contract with him. If the choice had no retroactive 
 effect he would only have a right of damages against the vendor. 
 Of course the purchaser may, according to circumstances, be pro- 
 tected if X was a movable thing, by the rule en fait de meubles 
 la possession vaut titre, and if X was an immoveable property, the 
 second purchaser may be able to defend himself if the first pur- 
 chaser has not transcribed his title. (C. C. E. 611/737.) 
 
 (2) If the debtor who has sold property X or property Y 
 becomes insolvent, the creditor can revindicate whichever of the 
 two properties is chosen. 
 
 He does not need to content himself with a dividend. (Colmet 
 de Santerre, 5, n. 115, bis, VI; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1077.) 
 
 Obligation may appear to be alternative without really 
 
 being so. 
 
 An obligation may be couched in an alternative form, and yet 
 may not be a true alternative obligation. The French Code says: 
 The obligation is pure and simple, although contracted in an 
 alternative form, if one of the two things promised could not be 
 the subject of the obligation (art. 1192). The use here of 
 the word "subject" is clearly erroneous. It is persons who are 
 the subjects of obligations, and things, or, as the Egyptian Code 
 prefers to say, acts, which are their objects. 
 
 This mistake is corrected in the Code of Quebec. It says that: 
 An obligation is pure and simple . . . if one of the two things 
 promised could not be the object of the obligation. (C. C. Q. 
 1095. See Planiol, 2, n. 709.) If one of the alternatives pro- 
 mised is the delivery of an article which is not an object of 
 commerce, or is the doing of an act which is unlawful, the obliga- 
 tion is not null as a whole, but it is not an alternative obligation: 
 it is a pure and simple obligation to do the thing which is lawful 
 and possible. For instance, I promise to sell you either my black 
 horse or my brown horse for a certain price. Unknown to both 
 of us, my black horse was dead at the date of the contract. In 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 371 
 
 spite of its alternative form, the obligation was in reality a simple 
 obligation from the first to deliver the brown horse. 
 
 When one of the alternatives is to do something illegal a dis- 
 tinction has to be drawn. If there are two separate things pro- 
 mised, one of which is lawful and the other unlawful, and both 
 the obligations are distinct and .principal obligations, the unlawful 
 obligation can be eliminated without affecting the validity of the 
 remaining obligation to do the thing which is lawful. But parties 
 are not to be allowed to take advantage of the rule stated in* the 
 code in order to give validity to an unlawful obligation. If I 
 promised to commit a crime, or in default to pay you a sum of 
 money, you would not be allowed to sue for the penalty upon the 
 •argument that the obligation to pay the sum of money was per- 
 fectly lawful, though the obligation to commit the crime was 
 unlawful. There are not here two principal obligations; the 
 obligation to pay the penalty is merely accessory to the other. It 
 is the business of the courts to interpret the contract and to dis- 
 cover if, in the intention of the parties, there were two distinct 
 objects, that is, two distinct principal obligations, or if, on the 
 other hand, one of the objects, which is unlawful, was the prin- 
 cipal object of the contract and the other was merely accessory to 
 it. When one of the things promised is actually unlawful, but it 
 might well be that the parties believed it to be lawful, the obliga- 
 tion to perform the other alternative may, very possibly, be a 
 valid principal obligation. But when the unlawful character of 
 ■one of the prestations must have been manifest to the parties, the 
 presumption is that the other prestation was promised to secure 
 the performance of the first. (Demolombe, 26, n. 11; Colmet 
 <do Santerre, 5, n. 119, bis; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1046.) 
 
 Effect of the impossibility of executing one of the 
 alternatives. 
 
 In the preceding paragraph we have considered the case in 
 which, in spite of an alternative form,, there was, as a matter of 
 fact, from the beginning, only one thing promised; because the 
 thing promised alternatively was null ab initio. We have now 
 to deal with the case where the obligation was really alternative 
 At first, but ceases to be so because it becomes impossible to per- 
 form one of the things promised. The Egyptian Code has three 
 .articles upon this subject which are not quite identical with the 
 
 24 (2 
 
372 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 corresponding articles of the French Code. The articles in the- 
 Egyptian Code are: — 
 
 // one of the modes of performance becomes impossible, the 
 obligation subsists so far as the possible mode of performance is 
 concerned. (C. C. E. 97/151.) 
 
 When the option belongs to the creditor, and one of the modes 
 of performance has become impossible by the fault of the debtor,, 
 the creditor has the option of requiring performance in the pos- 
 sible mode or of claiming the indemnity due as a result of the 
 impossibility of performance in the other mode. (C. C. E. 
 99/153.) 
 
 // both modes of performance have become impossible by the 
 fault of the debtor, the creditor retains his option between the 
 two indemnities due for non-performance. (C. C. E. 100/154.) 
 In the French Code the articles are: — 
 
 L'obligation alternative devient pure et simple, si Vune des 
 choses promises perit et ne pent plus etre livree, meme par la faute 
 du debiteur. he prix de cette chose ne pent pas etre offert a set 
 place. 
 
 Si toutes deux sont peries, et que le debiteur soit en faute a 
 Vegard de Vune d'elles, il doit payer le prix de celle qui a peri la 
 dernier e (art. 1198). 
 
 Lorsque, dans les cas pre/vus far Varticle precedent, le choix 
 avait ete defere par la convention au creancier, 
 
 Ou Vune des choses seulement est perie ; et alors, si c'est san<s 
 la faute du debiteur, le creancier doit avoir celle qui reste ; si le 
 debiteur est en faute, le creancier peut demander la chose qui 
 reste, ou le prix de celle qui est perie ; 
 
 Ou les deux choses sont peries; et alors, si le debiteur est en 
 faute a Vegard des deux, ou meme a Vegard de Vune d'elles seule- 
 ment, le creancier peut demander le prix de Vune ou de Vauire,. 
 a son choix (art. 1194). 
 
 6'^ les deux choses sont peries sans la faute du debiteur, et 
 arant qu'il soit *en demeure, T 'obligation est eteinte, conformement 
 a Varticle 1802 (art. 1195). 
 
 Les wtemes principes s'appliqumt au cas o<u il y a plus de deux 
 choses comprises <i<nis Vobligution alternative (art. 1196). 
 
 The space assigned in the codes to this matter is out of pro- 
 portion to its practical importance. There is hardly any juris- 
 prudence. 
 
 The first rule on the subject is: — 
 
 If one of the modes of performance becomes impossible the 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 373 
 
 obligation subsists so far as the possible mode of performance is 
 concerned. (C. C. E. 97/151.) 
 
 The one mode of performance may have become impossible by 
 the fault of the debtor ; or by a fortuitous event, and this will make 
 a difference in the rights of the creditor if the option was with 
 him. It is necessary therefore to distinguish between the case 
 when the option belongs to the debtor, and the case when the 
 •option belongs to the creditor. 
 
 (a) When the option belongs to the debtor. * 
 
 If one of the two things which were promised alternatively 
 has perished, there is left a simple obligation to deliver the re- 
 maining thing. It still remains possible for the debtor to fulfil 
 his obligation literally, because he promised to deliver one of two 
 things in his option and this he can do. He is not allowed to say: 
 " I prefer to pay the Value of the thing that has perished," and it 
 is immaterial in this case whether the thing perished by a 
 fortuitous event or by the fault of the debtor. The right of the 
 •creditor was from the beginning only to receive one of the two 
 things, and if he gets the one which remains his claim is satisfied. 
 But let us suppose that both things have perished. 
 
 Here we must distinguish between the case where both things 
 perished simultaneously, and the case where one of them perishes 
 first and the other afterwards, and in both these cases it makes a 
 difference whether the debtor was in fault or not. 
 
 If the two things perished simultaneously without the fault of 
 the debtor, seeing that the loss necessarily comprises the object 
 of the obligation, because, although it was as yet indeterminate, it 
 was one of the two things and they have both gone, the obligation 
 is extinguished by impossibility of performance. (Colmet de 
 Santerre, 5, n. 123.) 
 
 If the creditor has paid the price the debtor must give it back. 
 For by the Egyptian law, .when an obligation is dissolved in con- 
 sequence of impossibility of performance, the correlative obliga- 
 tions are in like manner dissolved. (C. C. E. 179/242. The 
 French law is different . Planiol, % n . 621 ; D . N . C . C . art H 1 302, 
 n. 7; supra, p. 316, and infra, p. 476.) 
 
 If the two things had perished together, and this was by the 
 fault of the debtor, he can liberate himself by paying the value 
 of either of them, seeins: that the choice was with him. 
 
374 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But suppose the destruction of the two things was not simul- 
 taneous. The French Code says as to this case: — 
 
 Si toutes deux sont peries, et que le debiteur soit en faute a 
 regard dc rune d'ettes, it doit pay,er le prix de celle qui a peri la 
 derniere. (C. C. F. 1193. Suppose it was by the fault of 
 the debtor that the second thing perished. This is the clearest 
 case. 
 
 The destruction of the first thing made the obligation pure 
 and simple. He was bound to deliver the second thing, just as if 
 this had been the extent of his obligation from the beginning. 
 And, if by his fault he cannot perform his obligation, then, accord- 
 ing to the general principle, he must pay the value of the thing 
 which he was bound to deliver, and we must add that he will be 
 liable in damages over and above this value if such damages are 
 proved. (Larombiere on art. 1193, n. 5; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig~ 
 2,n. 1089; C.C. E. 178/241.) 
 
 But what if it was the first thing which perished by the fault 
 of the debtor, and then afterwards, the second thing perishes 
 without his fault? Here there is more room for doubt. By the 
 perishing of the first thing the obligation became pure and simple. 
 It is now a simple obligation to deliver the second thing, and, if 
 this becomes impossible without the fault of the debtor, why are 
 we not to apply the rule that the debtor is liberated by an impos- 
 sibility of performance which has arisen without his fault? 
 
 There seems at first sight to be an inconsistency between the 
 rule stated in the French Code upon this point, and the statement 
 in the same article that the alternative obligation becomes pure 
 and simple if one of the things promised perishes. The provision 
 of the French Code in so far as it makes the debtor liable, is, 
 however, supported by satisfactory reasons which ought to prevail 
 in the Egyptian law, though the Egyptian codes are silent. It 
 is true that if one of the modes of performance has become impos- 
 sible the obligation is now a simple one to make the prestation 
 which remains possible, but, nevertheless, the fact that the obli- 
 gation was at first alternative affects the liability of the debtor. 
 
 The alternative character of the obligation was an advantage 
 to the creditor. He knew that if one of the things perished he 
 would still have a claim to the other. He had two strings to his 
 bow. The debtor is not entitled by his fault to deprive the 
 creditor of this advantage for which he stipulated. If the debtor 
 had not by his fault destroyed the first thing, then, in spite of 
 the loss of the second thing bv a fortuitous event, the creditor 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. 375 
 
 would have been paid. It is, therefore, in this ease also owing 
 to the fault of the debtor that the performance has become im- 
 possible, and, according to principle, he is bound to make good 
 the loss. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 74, note 13 ter ; Colmot 
 de Santerre, 5, n. 120, bis; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1090.) 
 But why should his liability consist in the price of the thing* 
 which perished the last as the French Code says that it does? 
 
 Pothier held that the liability of the debtor was to pay the prico 
 of the thing which perished by his fault, and not of the thing 
 which perished the last. (Oblig. n. 252.) Pothier's opinion 
 is supported by the high authority of Demolombe, as being sounder 
 than that adopted by the French Code. (26, n. 84.) 
 
 It is submitted that this is the Egyptian law. The liability of 
 the debtor is based upon his fault, and as regards the destruction 
 of the second thing he was not in fault. The French Code has 
 decided otherwise, apparently upon two grounds: (1) For prac- 
 tical considerations it is better to make the value of the thing 
 which perished last the measure of the damages, because it is 
 easier to ascertain what its value was. It may be difficult to 
 discover the value of the first thing which, perhaps, perished a 
 long time previously. (2) The debtor who has destroyed the 
 first thing by his fault thereby makes himself bound absolutely to 
 deliver the thing which remains. 
 
 It is by his own fault that he is deprived of an option, and he 
 must now be taken to have assumed all the risks. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 2, n. 1091.) Colmet de Santerre gives a third reason, viz., that 
 the debtor was within his rights in destroying the first thing, even 
 if he did so wilfully, and that if the first thing was of greater value 
 than the second it would be unfair to make the debtor pay this 
 greater value if the second thing happened to be destroyed later 
 by a fortuitous event (Joe. cit.). 
 
 This last argument, at any rate, does not seem to be convincing. 
 
 The debtor was not within his rights in destroying the first 
 thing. 
 
 It is true he had the right to choose whether he would deliver X 
 or Y, but, until he exercised this choice by delivering one of them, 
 the creditor had an interest in the continued existence of both 
 X and Y, and the debtor was not entitled to deprive him wilfully 
 or negligently of this advantage. The other reasons upon which 
 the provision of the French Code is justified are not without con- 
 siderable force, but, as the Egyptian Code is silent, the question 
 must be decided by general principles, and the solution of Pothier 
 
370 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 and Demolombe is more logical than that which the French Code 
 has chosen to adopt. 
 
 (b) When the option belongs to the creditor. 
 
 The Egyptian Code has two articles upon this subject: 
 
 When the option belongs to the creditor, and one of the 
 modes of performance has become impossible by the fault of the 
 debtor, the creditor has the option of requiring performance in 
 the possible mode or of claiming the indemnity due as a result 
 of the impossibility of performance in the other mode. 
 
 If both modes of performance have become impossible by the 
 fault of the debtor, the creditor retains his option between the two 
 indemnities due for non-performance. (C. C. E. 99, 100/153, 
 154.) 
 
 When the creditor has the option, the loss of one of the things 
 by a fortuitous event gives him a simple right to claim the thing 
 which remains!. There is, as the German writers say, a concen- 
 tration of the obligation. But when the loss of one of the things 
 was caused by the fault of the debtor the situation is different. 
 The debtor cannot by his fault deprive the creditor of the option 
 which he has given him. If the creditor prefers to claim the 
 value of the thing which has perished, instead of taking the thing 
 which remains, this is within his right. And if both things have 
 perished by the fault of the debtor, the creditor still has his option 
 in the sense that he may claim the value of either of the two things, 
 with damages in addition, because the debtor was not entitled 
 by his fault to prevent the creditor receiving the actual thing 
 from him instead of its value. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1094; 
 Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 121, bis 1.) So far the Egyptian Code 
 is in accordance with the corresponding articles of the French 
 Code. But the French Code goes further. It says: Oil les deux 
 choses sont peries ; et alors, si le debiteur est en faute a Vegard des 
 deux, ou meme a Vegard de Vune d'elles seulement, le creancier 
 peut demander le prix de Vune ou de V autre a son choix. 
 (C. C. F. 1194.) The words ou meme a Vegard de Vune belles 
 seulement have been very properly omitted in the Egyptian Code. 
 Why should the creditor have the right to choose between the 
 two indemnities when the debtor was to blame for the destruc- 
 tion of one of the two things, but was not to blame for the 
 destruction of the other? 
 
 The creditor has lost his option, it is true, but this is not the 
 
SEVERAL OBJECTS AND SEVERAL SUBJECTS. -'577 
 
 debtor's fault, and there is no reason why the debtor should com- 
 pensate him for this loss. It is the destruction of one of the things 
 by a fortuitous event which has deprived the creditor of the option. 
 Take the two possible cases: — 
 
 (a) The debtor is to blame for the destruction of the first thing, 
 and, afterwards, the second thing* perishes by a fortuitous event. 
 His liability ought surely to be the value of the first thing for the 
 destruction of which he was to blame. He had no right to deprive 
 the creditor of the option, and it cannot be said that he was exer- 
 cising a right in destroying the first thing. The creditor can, 
 therefore, claim the loss caused to him by the debtor's fault, and 
 the amount of this loss is the value of the thing destroyed. 
 
 (b) Or, suppose the first thing has perished by a fortuitous 
 event, the result of this is that the obligation becomes a simple one 
 to deliver the other thing. If, by the fault of the debtor, this other 
 thing perishes, he must compensate the creditor for this loss. 
 
 But there is no logical reason for allowing the creditor to claim, 
 if he prefer to do so, the value of the thing which perished without 
 the fault of the debtor. Under the Egyptian Code there is no 
 necessity to accept a solution in favour of which so little can be 
 said. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 121, bis 1; Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 75, note 13, quinquies.) 
 
378 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 CHAPTER XX. 
 
 FACULTATIVE OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Neither the Egyptian Code nor the French Code makes the 
 slightest reference to the facultative obligation, although in fact 
 this type of obligation is not uncommon, and it requires to be 
 carefully distinguished from the alternative obligation with which 
 it may easily be confused. M. Planiol, who speaks of the alter- 
 native obligation with a little spite, says that the facultative obli- 
 gations have a practical interest which is entirely wanting to the 
 alternative obligation, and he complains with reason that the 
 French Code devotes no less than eight articles to the alternative 
 obligation, and passes over facultative obligations without a word. 
 (2,n.711.) 
 
 Definition. 
 
 A facultative obligation is one in which a single prestation is 
 due, but the debtor has the right if he chooses to substitute another 
 prestation in its place. 
 
 Distinction between the facultative obligation and the 
 alternative obligation. 
 
 In the alternative obligation, as we have seen, there are two 
 objects; it is a composite obligation. There are, as the old writers 
 said, two things in obligatione. But in the facultative obligation 
 there is only one thing due. The debtor is bound only to one 
 thing. One thing only is in obligatione, but when it comes to the 
 payment the debtor can substitute something else. The other 
 thing which may be substituted is not in obligatione, but in facili- 
 tate solutionis. 
 
 The prestation which the debtor has the right or faculty to 
 
 substitute for that which he promised is a sort of accessory object. 
 
 He can use it as (a, means of escape from his obligation. (Pothier, 
 
 06%. n. 244; B.-L. et Barde, 2, nos. 1048, seq.; D. N. C. C. 
 
 art. 1189, n. 25.) To take an example from the Roman law: 
 
 If a slave had caused damage to a third party by his fault the 
 
 owner of the slave could be sued for damages. 
 
FACULTATIVE OBLIGATIONS. :;?!> 
 
 But if he was found liable, he might, if he chose, instead of 
 paying the damages, hand over the slave to the plaintiff. This 
 was called making a noxal surrender. (Gaius, 4, 75; Dig. 47. 
 2. 62. See Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. pp. 94, 469, 682.) 
 
 Examples of facultative obligations. 
 
 Examples of facultative obligations are to be found in the codes. 
 
 One illustration is when an immoveable, upon which a hypothec 
 has been created, perishes or deteriorates by a fortuitous event in 
 such a way as to render the security doubtful. Here the debtor 
 must pay the debt although it is not due, but he can liberate 
 himself if he offers a sufficient hypothec upon another immoveable. 
 (C. C. E. 562/686; C. C. F. 2131; Planiol, 2, n. 713.) And 
 the obligation of the third-party holder — tiers detent eur — who is 
 sued by the hypothecary creditor, is likewise facultative. 
 
 He must give up the immoveable unless he prefers to pay the 
 debt. (C. C. E. 574/697; C. C. F. 2168.) 
 
 Another illustration can be taken from the commercial law: 
 The drawers and the endorsers of a bill of exchange engage jointly 
 and severally that it shall be accepted and paid at maturity. But 
 if the person upon whom the bill is drawn refuses to accept it, the 
 holder can get the bill protested for non-acceptance. The effect of 
 this is that the drawer and the endorsers become bound to find 
 security for the bill at maturity. But they may, if they prefer it, 
 pay the amount of the bill and expenses at once. (Co mm. C. E. 
 119, 125. See Com. C. F. 120; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1049; Lyon-Caen et Renault, Manuel de Droit Commercial, 
 11th ed. n. 628.) Facultative obligations are not often created 
 by contract, but they are not infrequently created by wills. A 
 testator may, for example, leave a house to a legatee, but say that 
 if the heir prefers to pay to the legatee a certain sum of money 
 he shall not need to deliver the house. 
 
 Practical consequences of the distinction between facultative 
 and alternative obligations. 
 
 (1) In the alternative obligation, if one of the two things 
 promised is an immoveable and the other is a moveable, we cannot 
 say whether the obligation will be moveable or immoveable until 
 the choice is made. 
 
 But when the obligation is facultative, its character as moveable 
 or immoveable is clear from the first. If the thing promised — the 
 
380 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 thing- in obligation* — is an immoveable, the obligation will be 
 an immoveable one without any regard to the quality of the thing 
 which is in facilitate solutionis. 
 
 (2) In the facultative obligation, if the thing in obligatione 
 perishes without the fault of the debtor, and before he is in default, 
 the obligation is extinguished, and the debtor is liberated, for he 
 has only promised one thing, and, by no fault of his, it has become 
 impossible to perform it. Whereas, as we have seen, if the 
 obligation had been an alternative one, and one of the things had 
 perished, the debtor would have remained bound to deliver the 
 other. 
 
 (3) If the thing promised in the facultative obligation could 
 not be the object of an obligation because it was unlawful or 
 impossible, the obligation is null ab initio. It is immaterial that 
 the prestation which was in facilitate solutionis was lawful and 
 possible. This was only a means by which the debtor oould 
 liberate himself from the other prestation, and ho does not, in this 
 case, need any such means of liberation. 
 
 (4) In an action by the creditor for fulfilment of the obligation, 
 he must sue for the single thing which is due, without mentioning 
 the thing by means of which the debtor can liberate himself, and 
 the defendant can only be condemned to pay the thing which is 
 due. But the debtor can liberate himself either before or after 
 judgment by offering the thing which is in facilitate solutionis. 
 (Douai, 21 mars 1891, D. 92. 2. 549.) In an alternative obli- 
 gation, when the choice is with the debtor, the creditor is bound to 
 sue for either of the two things alternatively, for otherwise he 
 would be exercising the choice which belongs to the debtor. (On 
 these distinctions generally, see Larombiere, art. 1196, n. 3; 
 Laurent, 17, n. 226; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 72; B.-L. et 
 Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1051.) 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 381 
 
 CHAPTER XXI. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 
 
 It is very common for the parties to a contract to agree that, if 
 the contract is not fulfilled, or is not fulfilled within a certain time, 
 the debtor shall pay a certain determinate amount by way of 
 penalty . 
 
 This is called a penal clause, and the obligation to pay the 
 penalty is spoken of in the Egyptian Code as the penal obligation. 
 (0. C. E. 98/152.) Sometimes a testator or a donor inserts a 
 penal clause in the will or the gift in order to compel the heirs or 
 the donee to carry out some purpose which he has in mind. (See 
 Amiens, 26 fevr. 1896, S. 97. 2. 130.) 
 
 And, besides these cases, the non-performance of an obligation 
 casts upon the debtor the legal duty of performing other obliga- 
 tions, such as to pay the damages for its breach, or, in some cases, 
 to allow the creditor by the authority of the court to execute at the 
 expense of the party who has broken his contract that which he 
 failed to execute himself, or, when his obligation was a negative 
 one, to undo something which he did contrary to his agreement. 
 (Supra, p. 220.) The Egyptian codes regard these obligations 
 prescribed by law as analogous to the penalty which the parties 
 may have fixed by contract. It calls them all penal obligations. 
 (C. C. E. 98/152.) And there is, in fact, this similarity that in 
 all these cases the creditor has a choice between suing for per- 
 formance of the original obligation, if its performance is still 
 possible, or, instead of doing so, of enforcing the other obligation . 
 And in all these cases, also, the debtor may escape the payment 
 of the penal obligation if he performs the principal obligation 
 before he is in default, unless the penalty was provided for mere 
 delay- The Mixed Code is clearer upon this point than the Native 
 Code, but no doubt both intend to preserve the French law. 
 (C. C. E. 98/152; C. C. F. 1230 The means by which con- 
 tracts may be enforced apart from special stipulation of the parly 
 on the subject have been explained earlier, and we are here con- 
 
382 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 cerned solely with the case in which the parties to a contract have 
 agreed upon a clause of penalty to ensure its execution. The 
 French Code deals separately with this kind of penal obligation 
 under the head of Obligations avec Clauses Penales. 
 
 Definition. 
 
 The French Code says: La clause penale est celle par laquelle 
 une personne, pour assurer Vexecution dune convention, s 'engage 
 a quelque chose en cas d'inexecution. (C. C. F. 1226.) The 
 Code of Quebec with greater precision says: A penal clause is 
 a secondary obligation by which a person, to assure the perform- 
 ance of the primary obligation, 'binds himself to a "penalty in case 
 of its inexecution. (C.C. Q. 1131.) 
 
 Where should this subject be placed? 
 
 The French Code treats of obligations with a clause of penalty 
 as one of the kinds of obligations which are affected by sonne 
 modality, such as conditional obligations, alternative obligations, 
 and the like. The modality here is that the parties to the contract 
 have fixed what the damages for its breach are to be, instead of 
 leaving this to be determined by the court. Most of the French 
 commentators follow the arrangement of the Civil Code. It is 
 of course quite correct to say that an obligation w T ith a clause of 
 penalty is an obligation subject to a certain modality. 
 
 But the clause of penalty is so closely connected with the sub- 
 ject of damages, and the ways in which they are to be determined, 
 that many writers treat of obligations with a clause of penalty 
 under the head of damages. (This is done by MM. Aubry et 
 Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 187; by M. Planiol, 2, n. 253; and by MM. 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 23.) 
 
 No form prescribed for clause of penalty. 
 
 There are no sacramental words prescribed for the creation of 
 a clause of penalty . The court can infer from the terms of a deed 
 taken as a whole that the intention was to create a penalty. (See 
 Paris, 6 dec. 1877, D. 78. 2. 81; Req. 21 juill. 1885, D. 86. 
 1. 326; Trib. Comm. Caire, 1 fevr. 1913, Gaz. Trib. 3, n. 160.) 
 Nor is it necessary that the word " penalty " should be used. In 
 a Quebec case, where a deed said that the vendor of a business 
 should not carry on a similar business within a certain radius 
 a moins de payer comme dommages la somme de . . . it was 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. :j83 
 
 held that this was a penal clause, and, therefore, that it was not 
 necessary for the plaintiff to prove actual loss if there had been 
 a violation of the contract. (Girardv. Rousseau, 1909, K. J. Q. 
 36 S. C. 79. Cf. Nancy, 21 oct. 1895, D. 96. 2. 180.) 
 
 Purpose of clauses of penalty. 
 
 (1) The great advantage and convenience of a clause of penalty 
 is to prevent litigation by making it unnecessary to ascertain 
 the amount of the damages. The parties agree once for all that 
 if the contract is broken the damages shall be taken to be the 
 amount of the penalty. 
 
 (2) In the cases of promises and stipulations for a third party 
 when the stipulator has no interest and promised nothing, the 
 clause of penalty serves to give an action to a person, namely, the 
 stipulator, who without it would not have one. But in this case, 
 the clause of penalty is really the principal obligation. (Planiol, 
 2, n. 254; supra, p. 54.) 
 
 Clause of penalty strictly construed. 
 
 According to general principles of interpretation, clauses of 
 penalty will be strictly construed by the courts. It must appear 
 clearly that the event has occurred for which the penalty was 
 provided. In a French case, under a contract of employment, the 
 employee was to be entitled to payment of a year's salary, if, 
 after three years' service, he was dismissed pour un motif quel- 
 conque. The employment came to an end after more than three 
 years owing to the bankruptcy of the employer. It was held that 
 the employee was not entitled to the year's salary. The intention 
 of the parties was to give him a claim to a year's salary as a 
 penalty if he should be dismissed in an arbitrary or capricious 
 way by his employer, but not when the loss of employment was 
 due to such a cause as the employer's bankruptcy. (Req. 2 janv. 
 1907, D. 1907. 1. 88.) 
 
 Clause of penalty cannot defeat legal restrictions on rate of 
 
 interest. 
 
 When the debt is a money-debt the penalty stipulated for delay 
 in payment will be reduced to the maximum rate of legal interest 
 if it exceeds that amount, otherwise the prohibitions as to usury 
 would be easily evaded. (C. A. Alex. 28 janv. 1914, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 184.) 
 
384 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Position in the Egyptian Code. 
 
 The Egyptian codes contain only two articles on this subject, 
 and they are not placed together. One of them is among the 
 articles dealing with damages. 
 
 When the amount of the indemnity to be paid in case of 
 non-performance is determined by the contract or by law, the 
 judge may not award a smaller or a larger sum. (C. C. E. 
 123/181.) In this article the clause of penalty is regarded quite 
 correctly as a conventional liquidation of the damages. The 
 parties agree beforehand that if the contract is broken the damages 
 shall bo taken to be the amount which is stated. 
 
 The other article is interpolated rather strangely between two 
 articles dealing with alternative obligations. 
 
 In the case of a determinate obligation laid down by the law 
 or agreed upon as a penalty for the non-performance of another 
 obligation, the creditor, when the debtor is in default, has the 
 option of performance of the principal obligation or of the penal 
 obligation. (C. C. E. 98/152.) 
 
 The Egyptian legislator appears to have regarded the obligation 
 with a penal clause as a kind of alternative obligation. But it is 
 not correct to regard the obligation with a penal clause as an 
 alternative obligation. The debtor has not the choice between 
 performing his contract or paying the penalty. He can be made 
 to perform his contract if it is possible, unless it is a contract of 
 the kind which is not specifically enforced. And it is not an 
 alternative obligation in which the creditor has the option, because 
 he cannot sue for the penalty unless there has been a failure of 
 performance of the principal obligation. The penalty, as Planiol 
 well expresses it, is only a pis aller which presupposes a definite 
 non -performance of the principal obligation. (2, n. 259.) 
 
 An alternative obligation has two objects of which the party 
 who has the choice can select one. The objects are on the same 
 footing, they are both principal prestations, and if one of them 
 becomes impossible without the fault of the debtor, the other one 
 is still due. But in an obligation with a clause of penalty thene 
 is only one object: the obligation to pay the penalty is merely 
 accessory. And if the performance of the principal obligation 
 becomes impossible without the fault of the debtor, the accessory 
 obligation to pay the penalty falls to the ground. If I undertake 
 to deliver to you my black horse or my brown horse in your 
 option, the accidental death of my black horse leaves me still. 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 385 
 
 bound to deliver the other. But if I undertake to deliver to you 
 my horse or to pay L. E. 100, the death of my horse without my 
 fault, and before I am in default to deliver it, will free me from 
 all liability. I am not bound to pay the penalty. (Aubry eit Rau, 
 5th ed 4, p. 190. No doubt the Egyptian legislator intends 
 the same, for, otherwise, he would not speak of the penal obliga- 
 tion as being attached to a ''principal obligation." (C. C. E. 
 98/152.) In the alternative obligation there is no principal 
 obligation to which another is accessory. Both obligations are 
 principal. 
 
 Obligation with penal clause distinguished from 
 facultative obligation. 
 
 Nor must the obligation with a penal clause be confused with 
 the facultative obligation. It resembles that form of obligation 
 in this respect that it has only one object, and that if this becomes 
 impossible, the obligation is extinguished. But in the faculta- 
 tive obligation the debtor is free to choose. He has reserved to 
 himself the right of substituting something in place of the pres- 
 tation promised. But when the debtor has bound himself under 
 a clause of penalty he cannot, as has already been stated, choose 
 to pay the penalty rather than to perform his contract. He must 
 perform his contract if it is possible. (Colmet de Santerre, V, 
 n. 162, Us 11; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1361.) 
 
 Obligation with penal clause distinguished from 
 conditional obligation. 
 
 There is one kind of conditional obligation which may easily 
 be confounded with an obligation with a clause of penalty. This 
 is when the debtor promises to pay a sum of money in the event 
 of his not making- a certain prestation. By way of illustration, 
 I promise to pay you L. E. 100 if I sell my house to anybody 
 except you. Observe, I do not promise to sell jo\x my house, and 
 you have, to begin with, no right of action at all. It is only in 
 the event of my selling the house to another that you acquire a 
 right of action, and then it is only the right to claim the hundred 
 pounds. I am quite free to sell my house to another if I sacrifice 
 the hundred pounds. 
 
 Contrast with this another case. I promise to do a certain work 
 for you. subject to a penalty of L. E. 100 if I do not fulfil nry 
 contract , 
 
 w.— vol. ii. 25 . 
 
386 THE LAW OP OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Here you acquire a vighi from the date of the contract. You 
 can sue me to make .me fulfil my contract, and I cannot say: "I 
 will not do what I have promised, but I will pay the hundred 
 pounds instead," unless, indeed, the contract is one of those the 
 specific performance of which cannot be enforced. (Colmet de 
 Santerre, I.e.; Laurent, 17, n. 431; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1362; Cass. 14 juill. 1869, S. 69. 1. 411, D. 69. 1. 346, 
 .Journal du Palais, 69, p. 1072.) 
 
 Accessory character of the penal clause. 
 
 The French Code brings out clearly the. fact that the penal 
 clause is a. secondary or accessory obligation. It is "to ensure 
 the execution of a contract." (C. C. F. 1226.) This way of ex- 
 pressing it is perhaps open to criticism. In the Roman law the 
 penal clause was frequently attached to obligations which were 
 noi enforceable by the civil law. (Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 
 661.) In such a case, it was quite correct to say that the penal 
 clause served to ensure the execution. But in the modern law the 
 principal obligation is obligatory in itself, and its execution can 
 be enforced. The penal clause is not to make it enforceable, 
 except in the sense that it gives an additional motive to the debtor 
 to perform his contract. 
 
 The principles which apply to obligations with a penal clause 
 are almost all of them consequences which result from its accessory 
 character. 
 
 (1) Must be valid principal obligation. 
 
 In the first place, there must be a valid principal obligation, 
 the non-performance of which would render the debtor liable to 
 pay damages. The penalty which the parties have agreed upon 
 is to come in place of these damages. If the principal obligation 
 is null, the penal clause is likewise null. If the principal obliga- 
 tion is rescinded, the penal clause cannot be enforced, for an 
 accessory obligation cannot exist without a principal obligation 
 to support it. If it were not so, it would be easy to evade the laws 
 which prohibit certain contracts. For instance, a promise of 
 marriage is not enforceable, and if a penalty is stipulated in the 
 event of failure to carry out the promise, the penalty cannot be 
 recovered by an action. (Aubry et Rau, 5th cd. 4, p. 188; 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 23; Dijon, 27 mai 1892, D. 93. 2. 183; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1227, nos. 1 seq.) 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 387 
 
 The French Code has an express article: La nullite de V obli- 
 gation principale entraine celle de la clause penale. ('. C. F. 
 1227.) 
 
 To the rule that unless there is a valid principal obligation 
 there cannot be a valid clause of penalty there is no exception. 
 But there are certain cases which are so considered by many 
 authorities. Two of these apparent exceptions belong to the law 
 of stipulations pour autrui. If I promise that A shall perform a 
 certain prestation in your favour, you have no action either against 
 me or A, because A was no party to the contract, and I promise 
 nothing on my own account. 
 
 But if I promise that A shall do something for you, or, if not, 
 that I shall pay you a penalty, you will have an action against 
 me for the penalty if A fails to make the performance. 
 
 Conversely, if I stipulate that you shall pay something to A, 
 no right of action is created either in favour of- me or of A. But 
 if I stipulate that you shall pay something to A, or, in default, 
 that you shall pay me a penalty, I shall have a good claim for the 
 penalty in the event of your non-performance. (C. C. F. 1119, 
 and supra, p. 53.) In both these cases, there is apparently a 
 valid penal clause attached to an obligation which is null. There 
 seems to be an exception to the broad rule stated in the French 
 Code, la nullite de V obligation principale entraine celle de l<i clause 
 penale. (C. C. F. 1227.) Hiovv are we to explain these ap- 
 parent exceptions to the rule? According to the general view 
 they are really exceptions. If I promise that A shall do some- 
 thing, the reason why you have no action against me is simply 
 that I have promised nothing. But if I have promised to pay 
 a penalty I am in the same position as if I had guaranteed that 
 A should perform the prestation, and I make a promise in my 
 own name to pay the penalty if he fails to do so. And, in the 
 other case, if I stipulate from you that you shall do something in 
 favour of A, the reason why I have no action is because I have jno 
 pecuniary interest. This defect is cured, however, if you promise 
 to pay me a penalty if you do not make the performance to A. 
 
 As MM. Aubry et Rau express it: Where the inefficwy of 
 the principal obligation is due to a want of interest on the part 
 of the stipndator the addition of a penal clause 'is made with the 
 precise object of supplying this interest. (5th ed. 4, p. 188.) 
 This explanation is accepted in the Code of Quebec which provides 
 .the nullity of the primary obligation for any other cause than 
 
 '25 '2 
 
388 THE LA.W OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 want of interest, carries with it that of the penal clause. 
 (C. C. Q. 1132.) 
 
 This way of regarding the matter is, however, not satisfactory. 
 If I promise that A shall do something in your favour, or that I . 
 will pay you L. E. 100, there is from the first only one obligation, 
 viz., the obligation on my part to pay L. E. 100 in a certain 
 event. It is a conditional debt but not an accessory one. It is 
 not an example of the penal obligation in the sense under dis- 
 cussion. You, the creditor, never have the option of claiming 
 performance from A. My promise to pay the L. £. 100 is a 
 principal conditional obligation. (Larombiere, art. 1227, n. 6; 
 Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1359.) Another appa- 
 rent exception to the rule that unless there is a valid principal 
 obligation there can be no valid penal obligation, is in the case of' 
 the sale by a vendor of a thing which he knew not to be his 
 property. In this case if the purchaser believed that the 'vendor 
 was the owner of the thing he can claim compensation, although 
 the sale is null. (C. C. E. 265/334; C. C. F. 1599.) And, 
 no doubt, in such a case, if a clause of penalty had been inserted, 
 the purchaser might claim the penalty instead of the damages. 
 But here there is a simple explanation. The sale is not void but 
 voidable; it may be validated by the real owner of the thing. 
 (C. C. E. 264/333; Planiol, 2, n. 1428; B.-L. et Saignat, Vente, 
 n. 118.) 
 
 (2) The nullity of the penal clause does not involve the 
 nullity of th3 principal obligation. 
 
 The French Code says so in so many words, and this does not 
 need much explanation. (C. C. F. 1227.) 
 
 The principal obligation can subsist without the accessory, and 
 if the penal clause is null, the creditor can claim damages for the 
 non-performance of the principal obligation. In a French caa 
 a mother, as tutrix to her daughter, made a contract binding the 
 daughter by a clause of penalty to carry out a theatrical engage- 
 ment as an actress. It was held that this was in excess of a tutor's, 
 powers, at any rate, when the penalty was, as in this case, out of 
 proportion to the remuneration of the daughter. The clause of 
 penalty was null, but the principal obligation that the daughter 
 should carry out the engagement was valid, and she might be 
 compelled to pay damages for its non-performance. (Paris, 27' 
 juin 1889, S. 89. 2. 159, D. 90. 2. 206. 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. !}89 
 
 (3) Creditor may claim performance of principal obligation. 
 
 The creditor is not obliged to sue for the penalty when the 
 debtor is in default. He can, if he prefer it, sue for the execul ion 
 of the principal obligation. (C. C. E. 98/152; C. C. F. 1228.) 
 
 (4) The penalty comes in place of the damages. 
 
 The French Code says expressly: The penal clause is the 
 compensation for the damages which the creditor suffers from the 
 non-performance of the principal obligation. 
 
 He cannot claim at the same time the principal and the penalty, 
 unless the penalty has been stipulated for simple delay. (C. C. F. 
 1229.) The penalty comes in place of the damages; it is a sum 
 which the creditor agrees to regard as compensation for the loss 
 in the event of non-performance. Consequently, he cannot claim 
 both the performance and the penalty, or he would be getting paid 
 twice over. There cannot be, as the French writers express it, a 
 cumulation of the principal and the penalty. The presumption 
 at any rate is against the parties having this intention. But there 
 is no rule of public order which prevents the parties from agreeing 
 that a penalty shall be paid in a certain event, although the con- 
 tract still stands. It may be agreed, for instance, under the 
 terms of a contract of compromise, that if one of the parties 
 •disturbs the other in the enjoyment of rights given to him by the 
 eon tract, he shall be liable to pay a penalty. And such an agree- 
 ment can be enforced, although the contract of compromise still 
 remains standing. In such a case it is said that under the contract 
 the penalty was to be paid rato manente pacto. But such an 
 intention must clearly appear. The presumption is that there 
 is to be no cumulation. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 166, bis, 111.) 
 
 Penalty for delay. 
 
 It is very common in contracts to find a penalty stipulated for 
 delay in the performance. In a building contract, for example, 
 it may be stipulated that the work shall be finished by a certain 
 date, or if not, that a penalty shall be paid at the rate of so 
 much a day. In such a case, if the work is not finished within 
 the stipulated time the creditor can claim the penalty for the 
 delay, and also performance of the principal obligation. This 
 is not really an exception to the rule against cumulation of per- 
 formance and penalty. The obligation was not only to do the 
 work but to do it within a certain time, and the penalty stands 
 
390 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 in place of the damages caused to the creditor by the delay itself. 
 It represents moratory and not compensatory damages. It is due 
 although no loss is proved. 'Trib. Comm. Cairo, 24 inai 1913, 
 Gaz. Tn'l). 3, a. 328, p. 107. 
 
 When a delay for performance has been fixed by a judgment 
 and, after all, the obligation is not performed, the creditor can 
 claim the penalty for the delay and can also claim the damages 
 caused to him by the non-performance. But this will be so only 
 if the delay has caused him prejudice distinct from that caused by 
 the inexecution. If he had known at the date fixed by the contract 
 itself for performance that the obligation would not be performed, 
 he would have been entitled to the compensatory damages. By 
 having to wait until after the date fixed by the court to see if the 
 obligation would still be performed, he may have suffered mora- 
 tory damages, and in lieu of these he can claim the penalty. 
 (Cass. 11 mai 1898, D. 99. 1. 310.) 
 
 It may be that a penalty is stipulated for non-performance 
 and another for delay, in which case, if there is non-performanoe 
 after delay the creditor can claim two penalties. (Req. 29 janv. 
 1874, S. 74. 1. 245, D. 74. 1. 387.) Or it may be that in 
 the contract a penalty is fixed for delay only, and no penalty is 
 stated for failure to perform the obligation. In this case the 
 court is free to fix damages for the loss which has been caused 
 by the non-performance. The penalty fixed for delay affords 
 here no criterium of the damages. D'apres une jurisprudence 
 constante, la clause penal e premie pour la simple retard devient 
 sans objet si V obligation n'a pas ete executee, et il appartient en 
 ce cas au juge aVarbitrer les dommages-interets qui sont dus pour 
 V inexecution. (Trib. Somm. Caire, 11 avr. 1914, Gaz. Trib. 
 4, n. 308.) For example, A undertakes to pay a penalty if he 
 does not finish the building of a mill by a certain day. The mill 
 is finished within the time stipulated, but six weeks later some 
 of the masonry is found to be defective, and the mill cannot be 
 worked till this has been reconstructed. The court can fix damages 
 for this unsatisfactory work. (Cass. 13 juill. 1899, D. 99. 1. 
 524, S. 99. 1. 464.) 
 
 Doubt as to whether penalty is for delay or for 
 non-performance. 
 
 Where the contract merely states that it is to be performed 
 subject to the payment of a penalty, there may be a doubt whether 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 391 
 
 this means a penalty for non-performance or a penalty for delay. 
 This is a question of interpretation of the particular contract. 
 The amount of the penalty will as a general rule be a sufficient 
 guide. If its amount appears to be equal or superior to the 
 damages which the creditor would suffer by non-performance, 
 there will be a strong presumption that the penalty represents the 
 compensatory damages. If the penalty is of small amount com- 
 pared with the value of the performance of the obligation to the 
 creditor, the presumption is that it represents the moratory 
 damages. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 166 bis II.; Aubry ct Ran, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 189, note 6.) 
 
 It is to avoid such difficulties that when the penalty is intended 
 to be for delay it is generally stipulated that it shall be at the rate 
 of so much a day or so much a month. 
 
 Penalty not due unless debtor is in fault or in default. 
 
 From the principle that the penalty is essentially a sum fixed 
 by the parties which is to come in place of the damages caused to 
 the creditor by non-performance, it follows that the creditor will 
 not be allowed to claim the penalty unless the conditions are 
 present which would have entitled him to claim damages. If the 
 non -performance or the delay is due to a fortuitous event, the 
 debtor will not be liable to pay the penalty, because he would 
 not have been liable to pay damages; and this is so a fortiori if 
 the non-performance is caused by the act of the creditor himself. 
 (Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Obligations, 2, n. 1372; Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 190; Planiol, 2, n. 255; Req. 3 dec. 1890, 
 S. 94. 1. 315.) 
 
 And, seeing that the rule is that damages are not recoverable 
 so long as the debtor is not in default, the same principle applies 
 also to the penalty, and this is so whether or not a term is fixed 
 for the performance. The French Code has an express article 
 upon this point: Soit que V obligation primitive contienne, soit 
 quelle ne contienne pas un terme dans lequel ette doivc etre 
 accomplie, la peine n'est encourue que lorsque celui qui s'est oblige 
 soit a livrer, soit a prendre, soit a faire, est en demeure. (C. C. F. 
 1230.) The Egyptian law is undoubtedly the same although 
 there is no corresponding article, as the principle is involved in 
 the nature of a penalty. (See Trib. Coram . Caire, 24 mai 1913, 
 Gaz. Trib. 3, n. 328, p. 157.) 
 
 The obligation de prendre which is mentioned in the French 
 article means the obligation to take delivery. The article does 
 
392 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 not speak of the obligation not to do, because, as we have seen, if 
 the debtor has done that which he undertook not to do, there is no 
 necessity to put him in default. 
 
 And it is also clear that in other eases where damages are due 
 without the necessity of putting the debtor in default, the penalty 
 may likewise be claimed without putting him in default. And 
 this will be so when the debtor has bound himself to deliver or to 
 do something which could only be delivered or clone within a 
 certain time, and he has allowed this time to expire. (C. C. F. 
 1146; Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1370; Bourges, 
 14 nov. 1900, S. 1900. 2. 8. See supra, p. 211.) 
 
 The principle that, in the ordinary case, the penalty is not due 
 until the debtor has been put in default, has been applied in many 
 French cases of contracts to erect public works where penalties 
 have been stipulated for delay in their completion. (See Conseil 
 D'Etat, 18 mai 1888, D. 89.^3. 80; Conseil d'Etat, 8 aout 1896, 
 D. 98. 3. 10.) 
 
 Can the court fix a delai de grace? 
 
 When the debtor has been put in default the creditor has 
 acquired a right to claim the penalty. But the court has, no doubt, 
 power in the judgment to allow the debtor a moderate extension 
 of- time in which to jDerform his obligation, and, thereby, escape 
 paying the penalty. This j^ower will, however, be exercised only 
 in exceptional circumstances, and when the debtor's want of per- 
 formance is due to innocent misfortune. After the delay fixed 
 * by the court, if there has been no performance, the creditor can 
 claim the penalty. (Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 ii. 1371; C. C. E. 168/231; C. C. E. 333 415: C. C. F. 1244. 
 See supra, I, p. 365; and infra, p. 452.) 
 
 Can damages be claimed in excess of the penalty stipulated 
 or can the penalty be reduced if excessive? 
 
 The parties are taken to have lixed once for all in the clause of 
 penalty tin amount to which the creditor shall be entitled as com- 
 pensation for the n on -performance. And the court has no power 
 to vary this amount upon evidence thai the loss actually sustained 
 was greater or less than the amount of the penalty. The codes 
 are explicit upon this point. 
 
 When the amount of the indemnity to be paid in case of 
 non-performance is determined by the contract or by law, the 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 393 
 
 fudge may not award a smaller or a larger sum. (C. C. E. 
 L23/181; C. C. F. 1152. See Paris, 13 dec. 1000, D. 1903. 2. 
 253. 
 
 The old French law was different upon this point. (Colmet 
 de Santerre, 5, n. 165 bis.) 
 
 According to it and to the Roman law upon which it was based, 
 although the creditor had received the penalty it was still com- 
 petent for him to sue for damages which he had suffered in excess 
 of the amount of the penalty. (Dig. 17. 2. 41. 42; Girard, 
 Manuel 5th ed. p. 663.) 
 
 As explained by Pothier, the penal obligation could not lessen 
 or weaken the principal obligation. Consequently, if the penalty 
 did not make good to the creditor the loss which he had sustained 
 by the breach of the principal obligation, he was entitled to claim 
 the full damages and to take the penalty merely as a payment 
 on account. (Oblig. nos. 342 and 345.) 
 
 It is true that Pothier recommended the courts not to admit 
 too easily the claim of the creditor that he had suffered damages 
 in excess of the penalty. But, in his view, the courts had power, 
 according to circumstances, not only to give damages in excess 
 of the penalty, but also to diminish the amount of the penalty 
 if it appeared to be in excess of the damages suffered. The 
 intention of the codes is to reject both of these solutions of the old 
 law as being contrary to the intention of the parties. (C. C. E. 
 123/181; C. C. F. 1152.) 
 
 What the parties had in view was to avoid the necessity of 
 litigation. The damages were to be the sum stated as a penalty. 
 This intention would be defeated if the creditor could impose 
 upon the courts the duty of ascertaining the actual amount of 
 damages by pleading that the penalty was inadequate, or if the 
 debtor could do so by pleading that it was excessive. It is out of 
 respect for the true intention of the parties that the codes have 
 rejected the doctrine of Pothier, and have laid down the principle 
 that the courts are not entitled to award a smaller or a larger sum 
 than that fixed by the parties. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 165 
 bis; B.-L. et Barde, 1, n. 490.) 
 
 So, for example, in a contract of lease of services it may be 
 stipulated that if the employee is dismissed before the end of the 
 period of the lease, he shall be entitled to the whole of the emolu- 
 ments which he would have earned if the lease of services had not 
 been broken. And this penal clause cannot be modified by the 
 court. (C. A. Alex. 6 mai 1913, Gaz. Trib. 3,'n. 387.) 
 
394 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Cases where amount of penalty may be varied. 
 
 Notwithstanding the unqualified terms of the articles in the 
 French and the Egyptian codes, there are three cases in which it 
 is well settled that the amount of the penalty can be altered by 
 the court. And in France, another exception is created by the 
 loi du 27 dec. 1890, amending C. C. F. 1780, which will be 
 noted later. {Infra, p. 397.) 
 
 (1) When the principal obligation is to pay a sum of money, 
 and a penalty is provided; if the penally is of greater amount than 
 the maximum legal interest, which is in Egypt nine per cent., 
 the excess cannot be recovered. (Aubry et B,au, 5th ed. 4, p. 191 ; 
 C. C. E. 125/185. See supra, p. 244.) For otherwise, them 
 would be an easy way of evading the provision of the law which 
 fixes upon grounds of public policy a maximum rate of interest. 
 
 (2) When the non-performance has been caused by the wilful 
 act or dol of the debtor. It is against public policy that a man. 
 shall be allowed to exonerate himself beforehand either wholly 
 or partially from the consequences of his own wilful breach of 
 the contract. This wilful breach is called in the French law dol 
 or fraude, and in the English version of the Egyptian Code it 
 is called "fraud." (C .C. F. 1150, 1151; C. C. E. 122/180.) 
 Some writers prefer to confine the use of the word dol to denote 
 the kind of fraud which is committed in order to induce another 
 to contract, and to apply the word fraude only to the wrongful 
 infringement of another's vested rights. (Planiol, 2, n. 1069.) 
 If by stipulating a penalty, perhaps of small amount, the debtor 
 could escape all liability except for the penalty, although he had 
 wilfully broken his contract, the rule of public order would be of 
 little value. The law is clear, therefore, that a creditor who 
 proves that the breach of contract was due to the "fraud " of the 
 debtor, can claim damages Over and above the penalty stipulated, 
 up to the amount of his actual loss. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 190; Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 492, 2, n. 
 1373.) 
 
 And it is also a settled rule of the French law, which is followed 
 in Egypt, that there is a degree of negligence so gross that it is 
 assimilated to fraud. Culpa lata doJo cequipvpaiur . (Aubry et 
 B,au, 5th ed. 4, p. 190, note 7 bis; S'ourdat, Responsabilite, 1, n. 
 662 septies; Cass. 15 mars 1876, 8. 76. 1. 449, Journal du' 
 Palais, 76, p. 833, and note by M. Labbe.) 
 
 This principle has frequently been applied in France in cases 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 895 
 
 of contracts for the carriage of goods at sea in which a clause was 
 inserted limiting- to a certain amount the damages caused by the 
 loss of a passenger's luggage. It is held that such a limitation 
 does not exclude liability for fauts lourde. (See Cass. 13 aout 
 1884, D. 85. 1. 78, and the note by M. Bourcart to Trib. de 
 paix de Saint Vivien, 15 mai 1907, S. 1908. 2. 145; Cass. 2 avril 
 1898, D. 91. 1. 34. Cf. Paris, 24 mars 1877, D. 77. 2. 181; 
 Josserand, Les Transports, n. 908. and, in Egypt. C. A. 10 Feb. 
 1901, O. B. XI, n. 92.) 
 
 (3) When there has been a partial execution of the obligation 
 the courts are entitled to reduce the penalty. This is expressly 
 so stated by the French Code: La peine peut etre modifiee par 
 le juge lorsque V obligation principals a ete exeeutee en partie. 
 (C. C. F. 1231.) There is no corresponding article in the Egyp- 
 tian Code, but its effect is implied in the article which speaks of 
 the indemnity to be paid in case of non-performance. When 
 there has been a partial performance one cannot say that there 
 is non-performance. 
 
 The principle is that the penalty which the parties agreed upon 
 "was for total non-performance. They did not decide beforehand 
 what should be the penalty in the event of partial performance. 
 This is, however, a question of interpretation. It is quite com- 
 petent for the parties to agree that even if there is a part-per- 
 formance the whole penalty shall be due. Or it is competent for 
 them to fix a separate penalty as that which shall be paid in the 
 event of part-performance. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 191, 
 note 8 Us; Cass. 4 juin 1860, S. 60. 1. 653.) 
 
 Such agreements are unusual. In most cases the parties in 
 fixing the penalty contemplate only the event of total non-per- 
 formance. Here, there is no doubt the court may modify the 
 penalty where there has been a part-performance. (C. A. 4 dec. 
 1912, O. B. XIV, n. 18; C. A. Alex. 17 avril 1912, B. L. J. 
 XXIV, 282.) 
 
 But it is not in every case where there has been part -perform- 
 ance that the penalty is to be reduced. 
 
 (1) It must appear that the creditor accepted the part-per- 
 formance, for the debtor cannot insist on performing his obliga- 
 tion in part, (C. C. E. 168/231; C. C. F. 1244; Baudry-Lacan- 
 tinerie et Barcle, Oblig. 2, n. 1350.) 
 
 (2) The part-performance must be to the benefit of the creditor. 
 The Civil Code of Quebec states the French law upon this 
 
396 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 point more precisely than the French Code does: The amoivnt 
 of penalty cannot be reduced by the court. But if the obligation 
 have been performed in part to the benefit of the creditor, and 
 the time fbxed for its complete performance be not material, the 
 penalty may be reduced; unless there is a special agreement to 
 the contrary. (C. C. Q. 1135.) 
 
 The part-performance must have been to the benefit of the 
 creditor, or there will be no ground for any reduction. If the 
 contract were to cultivate so many feddans of land, at so much a 
 feddan, or to excavate foundations at so much a yard, subject to 
 payment of a penalty if the work were not finished at a certain 
 date, it is probable that a part-performance within the time 
 specified will have been for the advantage of the creditor, though, 
 even here, this is not necessarily so, because it may be that the 
 work done is useless to him, as it was essential to his purpose 
 that there should be complete performance within the specified 
 time. (See Cass. 23 mai 1898, D. 98. 1. 272.) 
 
 In a Quebec case a builder contracted to build two houses to 
 be completed by a fixed date, or to pay a penalty at the rate of so 
 much a day for delay thereafter. Both houses were commenced 
 and neither of them were finished by the date specified. It was 
 held that here there was no ground for reducing damages because 
 the work had been partly done. The unfinished building was of 
 no benefit to the creditor, unless he could have a useful occupation 
 of the part completed, which in this case was not possible. 
 (McDonald v. Hutchins, 1903, K. J. Q. 12 K. B. 499.) 
 
 There are, in fact, many cases in which a part-performance 
 will be of no advantage to the creditor. For instance, if a painter 
 leaves a picture half finished, the part-performance will, probably, 
 be of no advantage to his client. And when the penalty is acces- 
 sory tc an obligation not to do something, it would appear that 
 there is no room for the principle of reduction on the ground of a 
 beneficial part-performance. So, where a trader agreed to sell 
 certain articles made by a particular manufacturer, and bound 
 himself not to offer similar goods by any other maker, it was 
 held he must pay the penalty in full as he had broken his contract, 
 although he had sold some of the goods of the manufacturer with 
 whom the exclusive arrangement had been made. (Nancy, 21 
 oct. 1895, D. 96. 2. 180.) 
 
 Breach of an obligation not to do is in fact a case of total 
 non-performance. Even in the cases in which there has been 
 a part-performance to the benefit of the creditor which entitles 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 397 
 
 the court to reduce the penalty, the penal clause is not to be Left 
 out of consideration. 
 
 (3) In estimating the value to the creditor of the part-perfor- 
 mance, the court should take as a guide the amount of the penaltj . 
 that is the value which the parties set upon the total performance, 
 and the judgment should be for such a proportion of the penalty as 
 corresponds to the work which has not been done. For example, 
 if the debtor was bound to dig a canal one hundred yards long,, 
 subject to a penalty of L. E. 100, and he has dug the canal for 
 fifty yards, he should be condemned to pay a penalty of L. E. 50, 
 seeing that half the work has been done to the benefit of the 
 creditor, although the court might be of opinion that according 
 to the ordinary price for such work, a yard would be worth more 
 than one pound or less than one pound, as the case might be. 
 (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 168 bis, 11; Demolombe, 26, n. 671; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1351.) 
 
 (4) The French Code, as amended by the loi clu 27 dec. 1890, 
 creates another exception to the rule that the court cannot vary 
 the penalty fixed by the parties. (C. C. F. 1780.) That law 
 provides that in a contract of lease of services the parties cannot 
 renounce beforehand their right to claim damages for resiliation 
 of the contract. This provision of law based on considerations 
 of public policy, cannot be evaded by fixing a nominal penalty in 
 the event of the broach. (B.-L et Wahl, Louage, 3rd ed. 2, n. 
 3087; Trib. Comm. Seine, 9 sept. 1892, D. 93. 2. 545.) But the 
 Egyptian codes have no article forbidding the renunciation of 
 such claims in advance. 
 
 Can the creditor claim the penalty if the debtor prove 
 that no damages have been suffered? 
 
 According to the French doctrine and jurisprudence, the credit <>; 
 is entitled to claim the penalty without proof that any actual 
 damage has been caused to him by the non-performance, and it 
 would be no defence on the part of the debtor to prove that no 
 such damage had been sustained. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4. 
 p. 190; Baudry-Lacantinerie et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1373; PlanioL 
 2, n. 255.) 
 
 This conclusion seems to follow from the provision of the code 
 that the court has no power to reduce or increase the penalty which 
 the parties have fixed for non-performance. (C. C. E. 123/181: 
 C. C. F. 1152.) 
 
3U8 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Ii may appear from the facts proved that the damage sustained 
 was insignificant, and yet, if the parties have agreed that a largo 
 penalty should be paid for non-performance, the court is bound 
 to give judgment for this sum, however disproportionate to the 
 damage they may consider it to be. (C. A. Alex. 19 mars 1913, 
 Gaz. Trib. 3, n. 287. J Seeing that this is the law, it is illogical 
 to contend that if no damages have been suffered no penalty can 
 be recovered. It is plain that the law does not consider the penalty 
 as a sum which is to be equivalent, even roughly, to the actual 
 damage. It is the sum which the parties in their discretion have 
 agreed shall be taken as the value to the debtor of the non -per- 
 formance. It may be exorbitant, but the parties have agreed to 
 it. It may be a bad bargain, but it is a bargain. Unless the 
 debtor can succeed in getting his obligation set aside on the ground 
 of a vice of consent such as fraud, or on some other ground for 
 annulling; contracts, he must pay that which he has agreed to pay. 
 Xo doubt such a rule leads to harsh results in some cases. In a, 
 French case, for example, a poor actor was condemned to .pay 
 3,450 francs as a stipulated penalty for the resiliation of his 
 contract with a theatre manager, though there was no proof of 
 damage. (Nimes, 17 mars 1890, D. 91. 2. 52. Cf. Bordeaux, 
 19 juin 1903, D. 1906. 5. 29.) In a Quebec case a milk dealer 
 sold his business— ronde de hit — to another, with a covenant that 
 he would not sell milk to any of the customers transferred under 
 a penalty of 25 dollars for each customer. It was proved that 
 the vendor afterwards sold milk to twenty-three of the customers 
 whom he had ceded to the plaintiff, and he was condemned to pay 
 twenty-three times 25 dollars, no proof of actual damage being 
 required. Fortin v. Perms, 1912, R. J. Q. 43 S. C. 313.) 
 
 Where no damage is alleged or proved it may appear inequit- 
 able to allow a penalty to be recovered. On the other hand, the 
 value of clauses of penalty would be greatly diminished if the 
 rule "no damages no penalty" were adopted. The very purpose 
 of the penal clause is to prevent litigation. The parties agree 
 that, if there is non-performance, a certain sum shall become, 
 instantly payable. They intend to withdraw from the court the 
 power to estimate the damages suffered, and this purpose would 
 be defeated if the debtor who had broken his contract could refuse 
 to pay the penalty on the plea that the breach had caused no 
 damage to the creditor. This view may be regarded as settled 
 in the law of France and of Quebec. 
 
 The Egyptian jurisprudence both in the Mixed and in the 
 
OBLIGATIONS WJTII A PENAL CLAUSE. 399 
 
 Native Courts has been extremely inconsistent. The latest 
 decision of the Mixed Court of Appeal adopts the theory just 
 explained, and there is a recent judgment of the Native Court of 
 Appeal in Egypt in this sense, though the same court had pro- 
 nounced a few months earlier a judgment to the opposite effect; 
 and in its latest judgment the court has returned to its earlier 
 view of " no damages no penalty/' a theory which has now to be 
 considered. (C. A. 20 Feb. 1911, O. B. XII, n. 69. Contra, 
 
 C. A. 29 nov. 1910, O. B. XII, n. 24; C. A. 10 nov. 1915, 
 •0. B. XVII, n. 29.) 
 
 There is therefore, at present, a conflict between the Mixed 
 Court of Appeal and the Native Court of Appeal upon this point 
 which is considered in the following paragraph. 
 
 Conflicting opinion " no damages no penalty." 
 
 In spite of the considerations stated in the preceding paragraph, 
 there is a conflicting view upon this matter which is supported by 
 the following arguments: 
 
 (1) 'The penalty must be considered as coming in the place of 
 the damages suffered. It is an indemnity or compensation. (See 
 
 D. Rep. Oblig. n. 1595.) The French Code states expressly that 
 it is the compensation for the damages which the creditor suffers 
 from 'the non-performance of the obligation. (C. C. F. 1229.) 
 
 If no damages at all have been suffered, how can there be ;ui,\ 
 such thing as compensation or indemnity? It is admitted that 
 the penalty is not exigible when the non-performance was due 
 to a fortuitous event, although the codes are altogether silent as 
 to this. And this conclusion is justified by arguing that the 
 penalty is by its nature not claimable unless there has been a 
 wrongful breach of the obligation. May we not with equal force 
 contend that the notion of a penalty involves the existence of a 
 loss which is to be made good? 
 
 (2) If the creditor has suffered no damage the obligation to 
 pay the penalty is without a cause. 
 
 (3) To award a sum of money to a person who has suffered no 
 damage is contrary to the general rule: Nul ne pent s'&wichir 
 sans cause aux depens d'autrui. These arguments have prevailed 
 with the Mixed Court of Appeal in several cases, but in the 
 most recent decision of that court they have been rejected. In 
 one case the rule is thus stated: La clause penale cesse de sortir 
 effet lorsque Vabsence de dommage pour le creancier resulte elaire- 
 ment des elements acquis am proces on de faits que le debitew est 
 
400 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 a meme de prouver. (C. A. Alex. 17 avril 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 
 282. Cf. C. A. Alex. 12 avril 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 254; 
 C. A. Alex. 12 nov. 1908, B. L. J. XXI, 9; C. A. Alex. 1 
 mars 1900, B. L. J. XII, 140; C. A. Alex. 14 juin 1900, 
 B. L. J. XII, 347; C. A. Alex. 28 fevr. 1907, B. L. J. XIX, 
 139; C. A. Alex. 5 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 206; Trib. Civ. 
 Alex. 22 fevr. 1913, Gaz. Trib. 3, n. 218; C. A. Alex. 6 jam. 
 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 108.) And the latest judgment of the, 
 Native Court of Appeal is in favour of the view " no damages 
 no penalty." (C. A. 10 nov. 1915, O. B. XVII, n. 29.) 
 
 Even if we adopt this theory, it would seem clear, at any rate, 
 that the onus of proving no prejudice lies upon the debtor. Ho 
 has bound himself to pay a penalty for inexecution, and he has 
 broken his contract. If he wishes to escape his liability he must 
 show the reason. Upon this point it is submitted that the language 
 quoted above from the judgment of the Mixed Court of 17 avril 
 1912 is more correct than that used in another case when the same 
 court says: il est toujour s necessaire que la partie qui inwque 
 la clause penale justifie de V existence d'un dommage. (C. A. 
 Alex. 5 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 206.) 
 
 But in a more recent case it was held that la preuve du defaut 
 de tout dommage incombe a la partie qui pretend se soustraire 
 an paiement de la clause penale stipulee. (C. A. Alex. 6 janv. 
 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 108.) 
 
 But it is submitted, for the reasons stated above, that the view 
 that no penalty is recoverable when the absence of damages is 
 proved is a view which is erroneous. The Egyptian Code has no 
 article corresponding to C. C. F. 1229, which says, la clause 
 pen-ale est la compensation des dommages et inter -Us. And in 
 the latest case the Mixed Court of Appeal has rejected its former 
 theory on the subject. Celui qui a stipule line clause penale a son 
 profit n'est pas tenu, pour y avoir droit, de justifier d'une perte 
 quelconque : la clause penale fait la hi des parties, grace a son 
 caractere forfaitaire, sans qu'il y ait lieu de rechercJicr si le 
 creancier souffre on non un dommage par suite de V inexecution 
 de V obligation, la clause penale etant due des que le debit cur 
 est responsable de I 'inexecution . (C. A. Alex. 4 mai 1916, 
 B. L. J. XXVIII, 301.) 
 
 The argument that if no damage has been in fact caused to the 
 plaintiff, there is no cause for his obligation to pay the penalty, 
 and that to enforce its payment would be to enrich the plaintiff 
 without a cause, must be rejected. 
 
OBLIGATIONS WITH A PENAL CLAUSE. 401 
 
 When the parties agree to a penalty they enter into a kind of 
 compromise under which whichever of them breaks the contract 
 is to forfeit the penalty. Neither of them knows at the time which, 
 of them will benefit by the clause of penalty. The obligation of 
 each of them to pay the penalty has for its cause the identical 
 obligation of the other party. It is misleading in such a case to 
 speak of unjust enrichment. The equitable claim to restitution 
 arises only when the enrichment is without a cause. But in this 
 case there is a sufficient cause in the contract of the parties. (See 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1373, note 1.) 
 
 Penal clause in other legal systems. 
 
 Under the German Code, and under the Swiss Federal Code 
 of Obligations, the view of the old law that the court may modify 
 penalties has been retained. The courts have the power to give 
 damages in excess of the penalty if the creditor proves that the 
 penalty does not afford him complete reparation, and they have 
 also power to reduce the penalty if th« debtor prove that it is out 
 of proportion to the loss caused to the creditor. (Code Fed. Oblig. 
 arts. 161, 163; German Code, 340, 343.) In England, also, the 
 courts at common law have the power to reduce the sum stipulated 
 as a penalty if it appears unconscionable or extravagant. {Clyde- 
 bank Engineering Co. v. Yzquierdo y Castaneda, 1905, A. C. 6 r 
 74 L. J. P. C. 1.) 
 
 But it 'must be a penalty and not liquidated damages. In 
 England, where the parties did not intend to secure performance 
 of the promise by fixing a penalty in excess of the actual loss 
 which was likely to be caused by a breach, but merely intended 
 to estimate beforehand the amount of the damages, the courts will 
 not interfere. This is a case of "liquidated damages" and not 
 of penalty, and "there is nothing illegal or unreasonable in the 
 parties, by their mutual agreement, settling the amount of 
 damages, uncertain in their nature, at any sum upon which they 
 may agree." (Per Tindal, C. J., in Kemble v. Farren, 1829 r 
 6 Bing. 147, 31 K. R. 366.) The question of intention may be 
 a difficult one. It is not concluded by the fact that the parties 
 used the words "liquidated damages" or "penalty," respectively, 
 (See Magee v. Lavell, 1874, L. R. 9 C. P. 107, 43 L. J. C. P. 
 131; Willson v. Love, 1896, 1 Q. B. 626, 65 L. J. Q. B. 
 474; Halsbury, Laws of England, s. v. Damages, p. 329; Leake 
 on Contracts, 6th ed. p. 796; Mayne on Damages, 8th ed. p. 170.) 
 
 w.— vol. n. 26 
 
40*2 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Indivisibility as applied to obligations with a clause of 
 
 penalty. 
 
 The French Code contains two articles which deal with the 
 difficulty which may arise from the fact that the principal obliga- 
 tion assured by a penal clause was indivisible. (C. C. F. 1232, 
 1233.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is entirely silent upon this point. The 
 consideration of these articles in the French Code will be post- 
 poned until we come to the subject of indivisible obligations. 
 (Infra, p. 441.) 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 403 
 
 CHAPTER XXII. 
 
 JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Obligations may bo divided into those which are simple, those 
 which are joint, and those which are joint and several. In a 
 simple obligation there is one creditor and one debtor. In a joint 
 obligation there are two or more obligations which are combined 
 together, but each obligation stands on its own legs, and, though 
 there is only one title, there are as many obligations as there are 
 debtors or creditors. 
 
 If I promise L. E. 100 to A and B jointly, this means that I 
 owe L. E. 50 to A and L. E. 50 to B. These obligations are 
 quite distinct. If I pay A in full, and afterwards I become 
 insolvent, B cannot claim that A shall communicate to him any 
 part of what he has got. The debt to A may be prescribed, 
 whereas B may have interrupted the prescription of the debt to 
 him. Similarly, if A and B promise me jointly L. E. 100, there 
 are two separate debts of L. E. 50 each; and if A is insolvent, I 
 cannot claim from B more than the L. E. 50 which he owes. If 
 one of the obligations is null the loss falls upon me, and so on. 
 (B.-L. et Ba-rde, 2, n. 1107; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 17.) 
 When an obligation is joint the principle is that each of the joint 
 debtors is liable for an equal share. But this is a question of 
 intention. If three persons buy together a piece of land without 
 making themselves liable jointly and severally for the price, and 
 if their shares in the land are not to be equal, the liability of each 
 is, presumably, intended to be proportionate to his share. (C. A. 
 Alex. 18 juin 1914, B. L. J. XXVI. 447. See Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 17.) 
 
 When an obligation is joint and several different rules apply. 
 Instead of there being several debts, which for convenience are 
 created by the same title, we nave here only one debt, but it is 
 one debt which is due to several creditors or due by several debtors. 
 There is what French writers call solidarite or, as Pothier and the 
 older writers called it, solidite. The case of solidarity among 
 
 26 (2) 
 
404 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 creditors is a much loss common and loss important case than 
 that in which there are several debtors bound jointly and severally. 
 French writers speak of active solidarity to describe the joint and 
 several interest of creditors, and passive solidarity to describe the 
 joint and several liability of debtors. 
 
 (a) Joint and several creditors. 
 
 The rules of solidarity among creditors are thus stated in the 
 Egyptian Code: 
 
 Creditors benefit jointly and severally wider an obligation 
 when the agreement creating the obligation constitutes each of 
 them a mandatary of the others to receive performance; and in 
 such case the rules regarding mandate apply. (C. C. E. 
 107/161.) 
 
 Under the Egyptian Code, in this respect differing in expression 
 from the French Code, the creditors are not joint and several, 
 unless, under the obligation, each of them is given a mandate to 
 receive performance. The French Code says the title must give 
 each of them the right to demand payment of the whole debt, 
 and that payment made to one of them liberates the debtor., 
 (C. C. F. 1197.) Neither code intends to make it necessary 
 to use any special form of words. (Dall. Hep. Oblig. n. 1370.) 
 Each creditor may exact performance of the whole obligation 
 and may thereupon discharge the debtor. (See Req. 9 mai 1904, 
 D. 1910. 1. 332.) Unless one of them has instituted a suit, the 
 debtor may pay the whole debt to any one of the creditors. 
 (C. C. F. 1197, 1198.) Any one of the creditors who receives 
 payment may discharge the debtor, but a creditor cannot release 
 tin 1 debtor without payment, except to the extent of his own share 
 of the debt. In the .Roman law and in the old French law each 
 of the creditors might not only take payment of the whole debt 
 but might discharge the debtor of the whole debt without pay- 
 ment. (Dig. 45. 2. 2; 16. 1. 20; Pothier, Oblig. n. 260.) For 
 when there was solidarity, or, to use the Roman expression, cor- 
 reality among the creditors, each creditor was really a 'creditor 
 for the whole amount. It is true that, in most cases, at any rate, 
 if he received paymett of the whole amount, he needed to account 
 to the other co-creditors for their shares, Because he was either 
 their partner or their mandatary, but this necessity to account 
 depended upon the relationship between them and in no way 
 affected the debtor, and there may have been cases in which the 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 405 
 
 creditor who received payment did not need to account at all. 
 (Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 746.) 
 
 But the kind of obligation in which there are several creditors, 
 any one of whom can sue for the debt in full, and if he receives 
 payment can keep it all for himself, and in which any one of the 
 creditors can release the debtor without payment and so defeat 
 the interest of the other creditors, is so unpractical a form of 
 obligation that it is difficult to believe it can ever have been of 
 much use. The Code Napoleon which our law follows, proceeds 
 upon the much more probable and natural view that there is an 
 agreement between the creditors under which each creditor may 
 take payment of the whole, but simply as a mandatary for the 
 others to whom he must account for their shares. And he cannot 
 release the debtor without payment except as regards his own 
 share, for if he did so he would be giving away what belongs to 
 his associates. It is plain that the code presumes that in joint and 
 several interest, if one creditor gets payment of the whole he 
 must divide, and the presumption is that the creditors have equal 
 shares, although this is a presumption that may be rebutted. 
 (B.-L.' et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1165.) This makes it clear that 
 one creditor cannot novate or settle an action or arbitrate about 
 the whole debt. He can deal only with his share. 
 
 Can the debtor sued by one of the co-creditors set up in com- 
 pensation a debt due to him by the creditor except to the extent 
 of the share of the creditor? No, for otherwise this would be to 
 allow a debtor to set up in compensation against the mandator a 
 debt which the mandatary owes to him. And the Egyptian Code 
 savs we must follow the rules of mandate. (C. C. E. 107/161. 
 See Dall. Rep. Oblig. n. 2693; Panel. Franc. Oblig. n. 5812.) 
 It would be to prejudice the other creditors. It is not a sufficient 
 answer to argue that seeing that compensation is a kind of pay- 
 ment— compmser rest payer, — the creditor who is suing for the 
 whole debt may be met by the plea of compensation for the whole 
 amount. 
 
 For the result as regards the other creditors is not neeessarily 
 the same as if he had been paid. This creditor if he could be 
 paid by compensation, may be insolvent, and his co-creditors will 
 not be able to recover their shares from hi*. If he were paid in 
 money they could take conservatory measures at once. In France 
 the question whether compensation to the extent of the whole 
 debt can be pleaded is much disputed. (See B.-L. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 1145; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 22; Laurent, 17, 
 
406 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 n. 268. ) But the language of the Egyptian Code seems to remove 
 the difficulty. 
 
 Release. 
 
 The joint creditor has no mandate to release the debtor without 
 payment or to enter into a novation or a compromise of the debt. 
 Such acts can affect only his share of the debt. The debt remains 
 unaffected as to the shares of the other co-creditors. (Laurent, 
 17, n. 269; Hue, 7, n. 304; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, nos. 1152 
 seq.; C. C. F. 1198. See Req. 9 mai 1904, D. 1910. 1. 332.) 
 
 Interruption and suspension of prescription. 
 
 The only other provision in regard to joint and several creditors 
 which requires notice is in regard to the interruption or suspen- 
 sion of prescription. The French Code says: Every act which 
 interrupts prescription with regard to one of the joint and several 
 creditors benefits the others. (C. C. F. 1199.) This is quite 
 a natural rule. Each creditor being presumed to have an implied 
 mandate to do the bast for the others, an interruption of prescrip- 
 tion for the benefit of one of the creditors enures to the benefit of 
 all. It is the whole debt which is prevented from prescribing. 
 This principle does not apply to suspension of prescription. If 
 one of the creditors is a minor, prescription will not run against 
 him during the minority, but the shares of the others may be 
 lost by prescription. The theory of implied mandate cannot help 
 us here. It is reasonable to say that each creditor has an implied 
 mandate to interrupt prescription, but he has no mandate to be a 
 minor. The fact that the debt is joint and several is not the 
 same thing as its being indivisible, and there is no reason why a 
 special benefit which the law gives to certain persons who cannot 
 protect their own interests, such as minors, should be extended 
 to creditors who are of full age and in the enjoyment of their 
 rights. This seems to be the better opinion though there are 
 weighty dissentients. (Sic, Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2 7 
 n. 1149; Laurent, 17, n. 264; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 23, 
 note 11. Contra, Larombiere, on art. 1199, n. 3; Demolombe, 
 26, n. 171. The Egyptian law would appear to be the same as 
 the French upon both these points, though the Egyptian Code 
 is silent. 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 407 
 
 (b) Joint and several debtors. 
 
 This case is more common and more important than that of 
 joint and several creditors. It is dealt with in C. C. N. 108—116 
 and C. C. M. 162—172, with which we may compare C. C. F. 
 1200-1216 and C. C. Q. 1103—1120. The Egyptian articles 
 are: — 
 
 Debtors are not each individually bound for the whole of a 
 debt unless joint and several liability has been stipulated in the 
 agreement or pronounced by the law. 
 
 In such case the debtors are deemed to be reciprocal sureties, 
 each for the others, and also reciprocal mandataries for perform- 
 ance ; the rules regarding the contract of suretyship and of man- 
 date apply. 
 
 Debtors jointly and severally liable may be sued by the creditor 
 together or separately, except when some of them are liable only 
 at a fixed term or upon condition. 
 
 Default resulting from formal demand addressed to and pro- 
 ceedings taken against one of several debtors liable jointly and 
 severally take effect against all the rest. 
 
 No one of several debtors liable jointly and severally can in- 
 crease the obligation of the rest by his own act. 
 
 Each preserves the right of setting up such exceptions as are 
 personal to himself as well as those which are common to all. 
 
 One of several debtors liable jointly and severally cannot set 
 up a compensation to which one of his co-debtors is entitled. He 
 can only set up confusion of the obligation in respect of the share 
 of that one of his co-debtors whose joint liability has been extin- 
 guished by confusion. 
 
 He may not set up a release of the debt for more than the 
 share of that one of Ms co-debtors to whom the release has been 
 granted, unless the release be absolute, which shall not be pre- 
 sumed. 
 
 One of several co-debtors liable jointly and severally, who has 
 discharged the debt by payment or compensation, shall have a 
 right of recourse against each of the others for their shares. The 
 liability of such of them as are insolvent shall be divided among 
 those who are solvent. 
 
 The Egyptian Code does not state at the outset the general 
 character of the obligation as the French Code does. 
 
 There is a joint and several obligation on the part of the 
 co-debtors when they are all obliged to the same thing, in such 
 
408 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 manner that each of them singly may be compelled to the per- 
 formance of the whole obligation, and that the performance made 
 by one only discharges the others towards the creditor. (C. C. F. 
 1200.) This article brings out two characteristics of the joint 
 and several liability of debtors, viz.: (1) each debtor may be 
 compelled to pay the whole— singuli solidum debent ; and (2) pay- 
 ment by one frees &l\—unum debent omnes. But the article does 
 not bring out a third characteristic, viz.: (3) that each of the 
 co-debtors has an implied mandate to represent the others in all 
 that concerns the performance of their common obligation. Each 
 of them can do anything to improve the position of the others or 
 to protect their interests, but he cannot do anything to make their 
 position worse. (Larombiere, on art. 1200, n. 4; Cass. 16 dec. 
 1891, D. 92. 1. 177.) The Egyptian Code is more distinct as 
 to the last point. The debtors are deemed to be reciprocal man- 
 dataries for performance ; the rules regarding the contract of 
 suretyship and of mandate apply. (C. C. E. 108/163, 161.) 
 
 The illustrations of this principle will be given later. In the 
 joint and several obligation there must be the same thing due by 
 all the debtors and upon the same cause.. But it is not one obliga- 
 tion to which several debtors are bound; there is no identite du 
 lien. There are as many obligations as there are debtors. Hence 
 the nullity of one obligation does not affect the others and the 
 obligations do not need to be all identical in character. The 
 French Code says: An obligation may be joint and several, 
 although one of the co-debtors may be obliged differently from 
 the others to the performance of the same thing ; for example, if 
 one be obliged only conditionally while the obligation of the other 
 is pure and simple, or if one has been allowed a term which is not 
 granted to the other. (C. C. F. 1201. See Pothier, Oblig. 
 n. 263; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1117.) 
 
 The Egyptian article implies the same thing. (C. C. E. 
 109/165.) Accordingly, if the debtor who is bound purely and 
 simply pays the debt, he cannot sue in recourse the debtor who is 
 bound only conditionally, or after a term, unless the condition is 
 fulfilled or until the term has arrived. For he can have no higher 
 right than the creditor to whom he is subrogated. So, upon the same 
 principle, there is nothing to prevent two debtors being bound 
 jointly and severally, though the debt of one is for a larger amount 
 than the debt of the other, but in this case the joint and several 
 liability cannot exceed the smaller of the two amounts. For 
 example, by the same title A is bound to C for L. E. 1,000, and 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 409 
 
 B is bound to C jointly and severally with A for L. E. 500. 
 There is a joint and several obligation between A and B to the 
 extent of L. E. 500. By the same principle also two persons 
 may be bound jointly and severally though the debt of one may be 
 a commercial debt and that of the other a civil debt. So in France, 
 if a trader and a non-trader sign a bill of exchange or a promissory 
 note jointly and severally, the debt of the trader will bo a com- 
 mercial debt and that of the non-trader a civil debt. (Vand. 
 Franc. Oblig. n. 225.) In Egypt, however, bills are commercial 
 unless as against women non-traders, or simple cultivators. (C. 
 Comm. E. 2/2, 109/114; C. A. Alex. 26 avril 1893, B. L. J. 
 V, 188; C. A. Alex. 15 mars 1893, B. L. J. V, 10G.) 
 
 Presumption against joint and several liability. 
 
 Joint and several liability is either conventional or legal. There 
 are, as we shall see, a number of cases in which it arises by opera- 
 tion of law. Where it is conventional, there must be a clear 
 indication of the intention to create it. The French Code says: 
 An obligation is not presumed to be joint and several; it must 
 be expressly declared to be so. (C. C. F. 1202. See Cass. 31 
 mars 1909, D. 1910. 1. 19.) The Egyptian article though less 
 distinct, has the same meaning. The debtors " are not each in- 
 dividually bound for the whole of a debt unless," etc. (C. C. E. 
 108/162.) 
 
 Does the presumption against joint and several liability 
 apply to commercial matters? 
 
 This is a somewhat controversial point. The commercial codes 
 do not say that the presumption of the civil code is inapplicable, 
 or that in commercial matters there is a presumption of solidarity. 
 In Egypt, the Mixed Court of Appeal held in one case: En 
 matiere commerciale comme en matiere civile, la solidarite ne 
 pent residter que d"une disposition de la loi ou des conventions 
 des parties. 
 
 But according- to the prevailing view in France, when two 
 traders buy goods together for their joint account they are pre- 
 sumed to bind themselves jointly and severally for the price. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1175; Thaller, Traite 
 Elerwentaire de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. n. 1054; D. N. C. C. 
 1202, arts. nos. 37 seq.) And, in another Egyptian case, the 
 Mixed Court of Appeal held that solidarity is presumed when 
 
410 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 commercial operations are entered into by several persons collec- 
 tively and for their joint account. (C. A. Alex. 10 juin 1903, 
 B. L. J. XV, 342.) 
 
 Many codes now lay down ;as a general rule that in commercial 
 operations the debtors are presumed to intend solidarity. (C. C. Q. 
 1105; C. Comm. Ital. 40; and other codes referred to in B.-L. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1175.) 
 
 Joint and several liability by law. 
 
 Before taking up conventional joint and several liability, let 
 us enumerate the cases in which it is created by law. Passive 
 solidarity by law is imposed in express terms in various cases' 
 falling under all branches of the law, civil, commercial, and penal. 
 But subject to what has just been said as to commercial matters, 
 it does not exist unless there is a provision of law which clearly 
 creates it. It must be "pronounced by the law." This does not 
 mean that the words "joint and several" or solidairement, must 
 be used. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 33; B.-L. et Barde, 2, 
 n. 1174.) 
 
 Examples of passive solidarity in the civil law are: (a) That of 
 the architect and the contractor for the destruction of a building 
 within ten years. (C. C. E. 409/500.) (b) That of the judicial 
 sureties. (C. C. E. 499/609.) (c) That of the joint authors 
 of a wrongful act which causes damage to another. (C. C. E. 
 150/211.) Upon this last matter the Egyptian Code, like the 
 Code of Quebec, (C. C. Q. 1106) has settled a long-standing con- 
 troversy. 
 
 The French Penal Code makes the joint authors of a penal 
 delict liable jointly and severally (art. 55), but the Civil Code 
 has no similar provision as to the joint authors of a civil delict or 
 of a quasi-delict. 
 
 The jurisprudence admits the principle of solidarity in this 
 case, reasoning by analogy from the Code Penal, but the doctrine 
 for the most part refuses to accept the view that there is here 
 solidarity in the full sense. (See Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 33;' 
 Planiol, 2, n. 903; Req. 26 nov. 1907, D. 1908. 1. 139; Cass. 
 17 mars 1902, D. 1902. 1. 541, and the note; Cass. 16 juill. 
 1902, D. 1903. 1. 401, dissertation by M. Capitant; D. N. C. C. 
 Additions (1913), art. 1202, n. 54—5°.) 
 
 It is not necessary for us to enter into this discussion as the 
 Egyptian Code is clear. 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 411 
 
 It is also clear under the Egyptian codes, that when the damage 
 is caused by a person for whom another is civilly responsible, as r 
 for example, by a servant acting- in the course of his employment, 
 the person civilly responsible can be made jointly and severally 
 liable together with the actual wrongdoer. (C. C. E. 150 — 
 152/211—214.) 
 
 The French jurisprudence is in the same sense. (Req. 22 
 juill. 1891, D. 92. 1. 335; Dijon, 4 juin 1902, D. 1902. 2. 279; 
 Cass. 11 fevr. 1889, D. 89. 1. 316; and the note to Cass. 16 
 juill. 1902, D. 1903. 1. 401.) The joint and several liability 
 of wrongdoers to the victim does not imply that as among them- 
 selves their liability is equal. The joint and several liability of 
 wrongdoers belongs more naturally to the subject of responsibility. 
 The Egyptian Code does not, like the French Code, make joint- 
 mandators liable jointly and severally to the mandatary (C. C. F. 
 2002) or make joint-borrowers of an article liable jointly and 
 severally to the lender. (C. C. F. 1887.) 
 
 In the commercial law the partners in a partnership en nom 
 collectif are liable jointly and severally for all the engagements 
 of the partnership, though only one partner may, have signed the 
 document provided he has done so under the firm-name. (C. 
 Comm. E. 22/28.) 
 
 And all persons who have drawn, accepted or endorsed a bill 
 of exchange are jointly and severally liable to the holder for 
 payment. (C. Comm. E. 137/144. See C. A. Alex. 22 avril 
 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 342.) 
 
 In the penal law all the persons sentenced for the same felony 
 or same misdemeanour— delit — are jointly and severally liable for 
 the fines, the restitution, the damages and the costs. (C. Pen. M. 
 24. Cf. C. Pen. N. 44, which is less wide.) 
 
 Persons who without right use together, and in a common 
 interest, the property of another are liable jointly and severally. 
 (C. A. Alex. 19 mare 1903, B. L. J. XV, 207. Cf. Req. ler mai 
 1906, D. 1906. 1. 341.) So are the joint owners of a mitoyen 
 wall which falls and brings down a neighbour's house. (C. A. 
 Alex. 28 janv. 1903, B. L. J. XV, 111.) 
 
 So are the persons who fraudulently conspire to do an act which 
 causes damage. (C. A. Alex. 11 avril 1906, B. L. J. XVIII, 
 189; C. A. Alex. 17 mai 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 277.) 
 
 This will be so, for instance, in the case of co-vendors who 
 declare an immoveable free from all charges, when it is to their 
 
412 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 knowledge burdened with a hypothec. (C. A. Alex. 17 mai 
 
 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 277.) 
 
 In many eases it is not possible to determine the share of blame 
 attaching to each of the offenders. They will be liable each for 
 the whole to the victim, and, as among- themselves, in ecpual shares. 
 (See Req. 26 nov. 1907, D. 1908. 1. 139.) 
 
 When an action is brought against several defendants in which 
 the conclusion is for damages against them jointly and severally, 
 and judgment is rendered against the defendants with costs, does 
 such a judgment imply that the liability for the costs is likewise 
 joint and several? 
 
 The general answer to this must be in the negative. 
 
 A joint and several debtor has no mandate to injure the other 
 debtors or to increase their liability. 
 
 If he wrongously defends the action he is a plaidew imprudent, 
 and the costs which he incurs by so doing cannot be considered as 
 accessory to the debts of the other debtors. (Larombiere, art. 
 1202, n. 23; Pond. Frang. vo. Oblig. n. 301; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1202, n. 183; C. A. Alex. 3 mai 1900, B. L. J. XII, 235.) 
 But the court if it gives judgment against the defendants jointly 
 and severally, may, in awarding expenses, say that the expenses 
 are a titre de dommages et interets. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 35; Cass. 2 fevr. 1910, D. 1910. 1. 533.) And when the 
 action is brought against persons as being jointly guilty of a 
 delict or quasi-delict, and they are found liable in damages jointly 
 and severally, they may be condemned, likewise, to pay costs 
 jointly and severally, seeing that such a condemnation is merely 
 accessory to the principal judgment. (Req. ler mai 1906, D. 
 
 1906. 1. 341; Req. 12 nov. 1907, D. 1908. 1. 87.) 
 
 The cases of joint and several liability arising by virtue of the 
 law have now been enumerated. They will not be extended by 
 analogy. The presumption against joint and several liability 
 applies both to the case where it is created by some provision of 
 law and to the case where it arises from agreement. Accordingly, 
 it is generally agreed that the joint and several liability of joint- 
 borrower:- under the French Code cannot be extended by analogy 
 to joint-lenders, and that joint-depositaries are not liable jointly 
 and severally, seeing that there is no provision of law to that effect. 
 (Demolombe, 26, nos. 252, 255; Pond. Frang. Oblig. n. 285.) 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 413 
 
 Conventional joint and several liability. 
 
 In order to create a joint and several obligation by agreement of 
 parties the Egyptian ( 'ode says: It must be stipulated in the agree- 
 ment (arts. 108/162). In saying that the obligation is not joint 
 and several, unless it is expressly so declared, the code does not mean 
 that the words "joint and several" — solidmrement — are indispen- 
 sable, though it is safer to use them when the intention is to> 
 create solidarity. But the parties may use other -words, such as 
 that " each is to be liable for the whole," or that they " renounce 
 the benefits of division and discussion," and, in such cases, there 
 is a joint and several obligation though this precise term is not 
 used in the agreement. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2 r 
 n. 1174; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 32.) But there must be 
 no ambiguity about the terms used. (Douai, 20 mars 1882, D. 
 83. 2. 20; Cass. 15 juill. 1896, D. 97. 1. 109, Journal du Palais, 
 1830-1831, p. 74: I). N. C. C. art. 1202, n. 20; C. A. Alex. 
 22 mars 1900, B. L. J. XII, 173.) So the obligation of the co- 
 purchasers of an immoveable to pay the price is not presumed to 
 mean that they are liable jointly and severally. (Cass, ler dec. 
 1908, D. 1909. 1 . 420.) On the other hand, when co-vendors bind 
 themselves to deliver a thing, this obligation, being in its nature 
 indivisible, implies, or may be held to imply, that they are bound 
 jointly and severally. (See C. A. Alex. 5 avril 1900, B. L. J. 
 XII, 198.) 
 
 Conversely, even when the words "jointly and severally" are 
 used, it is still possible for the court to find that there is not a 
 joint and several debt, because, on a fair interpretation of the 
 deed as a whole, it may appear that this was not the true intention 
 of the parties. The words "joint and several," or solidmrement T 
 may be controlled by other words which show that the parties 
 did not intend to be bound jointly and severally. Where, for 
 instance, although the word solidairement was used in a contract, 
 it was stipulated that the creditor should not attack one debtor 
 until he had first discussed the other, thus showing that one of the 
 parties intended to be bound only as surety and not as principal, 
 it was held there was no joint and several liability. (Bourges,. 
 7 mars 1831, D. 31. 2. 158; Cass. 4 dec. 1855, D. 56. 1. 58;. 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1177. Cf. Cass. 15 juill. 
 1896, D. 97. 1. 109.) 
 
414 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Effects of joint and several liability among the debtors. 
 
 (a) Effects of principle that each debtor is liable 
 for whole debt. 
 
 The articles upon this subject in the Egyptian Code have been 
 already stated. (C. C. E. 109 — 115, 165 — 171.) As against the 
 creditor each of the debtors is a principal, and may be sued for the 
 whole debt. He cannot plead the benefit of division, that is, that 
 the creditor must begin by suing all the co-d.cbtors each for his 
 share. Nor, if the co-debtor" is a surety, can he plead the benefit 
 of discussion, that is, that the creditor must first take proceedings 
 against the principal debtor. Among themselves the debtors may 
 .be liable each only for his share, or the debt may be, as among" 
 themselves, the debt of one only, the others being merely sureties. 
 But from the point of view of the creditor the great virtue of joint 
 and several liability is that he can treat each of the debtors as if 
 he were the only debtor, bound to pay the whole debt. The 
 creditor is not concerned with their relations with each other. 
 (C. C. F. 1203; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1203; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 42.) 
 
 This right of the creditor to attack any one of the debtors and 
 to call upon him to pay the whole debt, does not, however, exclude 
 the debtor who is sued from the right of calling in the other* 
 debtors as warrantors. He may, by means of a dilatory exception, 
 obtain delay for this purpose. Pothier taught otherwise, though 
 he said that even in his time the debtor was, as matter of favour, 
 always accorded this right. {Oblig. n. 330.) It is obviously 
 equitable that this right should exist; the delay to the creditor 
 is merely of a few days, and the gain to the debtor is great. The 
 practice appears to be settled in this sense in France. (Demo- 
 lombe, 26, n. 316; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1204; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 43. Contra, Laurent, 17, n. 297. See D. N. 
 C. C. art. 1203, n. 11.) And even when the joint and several, 
 liability arises from a delict, as distinguished from a quasi-delict, 
 though the liability is of a penal character, the debtor who is sued 
 has an action in warranty against the co-offenders. For the 
 Egyptian Code makes no distinction. (C. C. E. 115, 150, 
 171, 211. Cf. C. Pen. E. 44/24.) 
 
 This is so in France also, though the liability in this ease is not 
 there generally regarded as a joint and several obligation in the 
 full sense. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. n. 1305; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 49, note 36 quater.) And when one of the joint and 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 415^ 
 
 several debtors is sued, the others, even although not called in, have 
 the right to intervene in the action at any time before judgment.. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1205; Aubry et Kau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 43.) 
 
 The creditor cannot, without the consent of the co-debtors, 
 divide the debt, and if he sues a co-debtor only for his equal share, 
 and the debtor insists on paying the whole debt, the creditor must 
 receive this payment, and the judgment will have the effect of 
 liberating the other debtors as regards the creditor, and of subro- 
 gating the debtor who has paid in the creditor's rights against 
 them. 
 
 Laurent disputes this upon the ground that the exclusion of 
 division is wholly in the interest of the creditor, and he may, 
 therefore, waive it. (17, n. 298.) But the other view seems to 
 be settled in France, and is supported by the argument that the 
 effect of the joint and several liability is to place each of the 
 co-debtors in the same position as if he were the only debtor. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1209; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 43; Cass. 25 mars 1896, D. 96. 1. 294.) 
 
 The creditor may sue one of the joint and several debtors, or 
 all of them together, or some of them only, as he chooses. And 
 if he sue several of them, they may all be brought before the 
 court of the district in which one of them has been summoned. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1212.) 
 
 (b) Effects of theory that each debtor has mandate. 
 
 The consequences of joint and several liability which have so 
 far been referred to, flow from the principle that the creditor has 
 the right to consider each of the debtors as liable for the whole 
 debt. 
 
 There are other consequences which flow from the principle 
 that each of the co-debtors has an implied mandate from the 
 others to represent them for certain purposes. The traditional 
 way of stating the extent of this mandate is to say that it extends 
 ad conservandam vel perpetnandam obligationem non ad align i- 
 dam. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 273; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 
 2, n. 1213; Agen, 28 oct. 1891, D. 93. 2. 540.) According to 
 a modern decision of the Cow dc Cassation the extent of the 
 implied mandate given to each other by the joint and several 
 debtors is to do anything which ameliorates the condition of all 
 of them, but nothing which can injure the condition of any of 
 
416 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 them, unless there is some exceptional provision of law which 
 allows this. (Cass. 16 dec. 1891, D. 92. 1. 177, S. 93. 1. 81.) 
 The Egyptian Code expresses the rule clearly enough: No one 
 of several debtors liable jointly and severally can increase the 
 obligation of the rest by his own act. (C. C. E. 111/167.) 
 
 Consequences of theory of mandate. 
 
 Default resulting from formal demand addressed to and pro- 
 ceedings taken against one of severed debtors liable jointly and 
 severally take effect against all the rest. (C. C. E. 110/166.) 
 
 When the object of the debt is a specific thing, and it has 
 perished, or can no longer be delivered, owing to the fault of one 
 of the co-debtors, or after he is in default, this does not free the 
 other co-debtors from their liability to pay its value. 
 
 But the debtor who is in fault is the only person liable to 
 pay damages over and above the value of the thing. For this 
 aggravation of the debt has been caused by him alone, and he had 
 no mandate to increase the liability of the others. If they were 
 all in fault, or in default, they would all be liable in damages as 
 well as for the value; and, conversely, if the thing perished without 
 the fault or default of any of them they would all be free from 
 any liability. (C. C. F. 1205; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1224; 
 Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 47; De Hults, Rep. Obligations, 
 n. 127.) An act which interrupts prescription against one of the 
 joint and several debtors interrupts it with regard to all of them. 
 (C. C. F. 1199.) So, an action brought against one of the 
 debtors interrupts prescription as regards them all, seeing that each 
 of them has a mandate to represent the others. (C. C. F. 1206; 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1214.) 
 
 An acknowledgment of the debt made by one of the co-debtors, 
 being an act of interruption, affects the other co-debtors as well. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1215; Req. 19 mai 1884, 
 D. 84. 1. 286; Agen, 28 oct. 1891, D. 93. 2. 540.) 
 
 But when one of the joint and several debtors has died, and 
 the act of interruption is in regard to one of his heirs, this does 
 not interrupt prescription as regards the other heirs, and it inter- 
 rupts prescription as regards the other co-debtors no>t for the whole 
 debt but only for the share of this particular heir who has acknow- 
 ledged his liability. 
 
 This is because if one of the joint and several debtors dies 
 leaving several heirs, each heir is liable only for a share of the debt 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 417 
 
 proportionate to his share in the succession. (' . ('. F . 2249; 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1218; Laurent, 17, n. 327. For 
 example, John and William are jointly and severally bound Lo 
 pay L. E. 10,000 to Thomas; John dies, leaving as his heirs in 
 equal shares, his two sons Henry and Robert. Thomas, the 
 creditor, sues Robert, and obtains an acknowL dgment of the debt. 
 This interrupts the prescription as regards Robert, and as regards 
 William also, because William is a co-debtor, but only to tin 
 extent of L. E. 5,000, because Robert as an heir was liable only 
 for half the debt. But it does not interrupt the prescription as 
 regards Henry, for he is not a co-debtor, and though he and Robert 
 are co-heirs, one co-heir has no mandate to represent another. 
 But this will not be the case when the original debt was indivisible 
 as well as joint and several, because in that case it must be kept 
 alive as a whole or extinguished as a whole. (C. C. F. 2249; 
 B.-L. ct Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1218; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescrip- 
 tion, n. 559.) 
 
 A demand of interest made against one of the joint and several 
 debtors causes interest to run against them all. (C. 0. P. 1207. 
 See C. C. E. 110/166.) 
 
 Another consequence of the theory of mutual representation 
 will be noticed later under the head of chose jugec. 
 
 Exceptions which a joint and several debtor may plead 
 against the creditor. 
 
 Each of the co-debtors preserves the right of setting up such 
 exceptions as are personal to himself as well as those which are 
 common to all. (C. C. E. 112/168.) The French Code says: 
 Le codebiteur solidaire poursuivi par le creamier peut opposer 
 toutes les exceptions qui resultent de la nature de V obligation , et 
 toutes celles qui lui sont personnelles, ainsi que celles qui sont 
 communes a tous les codebiteurs. II ne pent opposer les exceptions 
 qui sont purement personnelles a qxelqnes-uns des autre* co- 
 debiteurs. (O. C. F. 1208.) 
 
 Personal exceptions. 
 
 He may plead such personal exceptions as, for example, his 
 minority or interdiction, or that he was led into the contract by 
 fraud. 
 
 w.— vol: ii 
 
 27 
 
418 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Exceptions common to all the debtors. 
 
 Ho may plead any defence which strikes at the root of the whole 
 obligation, such as that the creditor has received payment in full, 
 or that the debt has prescribed. For such a defence is in its nature 
 common to all the debtors. 
 
 In this class come such exceptions as unlawful cause, defect of 
 form, condition not fulfilled, term not expired, payment, nova- 
 tion, release, prescription. 
 
 Exceptions personal to another debtor. 
 
 But he cannot plead that one of the other co-debtors was a 
 minor or had been led into the contract by fraud, or the like. 
 Seeing that he has made himself liable for the payment of the 
 whole debt, it is immaterial, in a question between him and the 
 creditor, that another co-debtor would have a good defence. 
 
 " Personal exception " does not mean same thing here 
 as in case of surety., 
 
 The French Code uses the same expression, purement person- 
 nelles, in speaking of the exceptions which a surety is not allowed 
 to oppose to the creditor. Le caution ne pent opposer les excep*- 
 tions qui sont purement personnelles au debiteur. (C. C. F. 
 2036, 1208.) 
 
 In spite of this, it is the prevailing view in France that the 
 words purement personnelles used in regard to the case of the 
 debtor and the surety do not mean quite the same thing as the 
 identical words used in the case of co-debtors. 
 
 It follows from the nature of suretyship that the surety can 
 set up the exceptions which the principal debtor might plead 
 himself when these exceptions are based on vices of consent. 
 
 He may plead that the principal debtor's consent was vitiated 
 by error, violence, or fraud. 
 
 And the surety may do so, even though he was bound jointly 
 and severally with the debtor. For his obligation as a surety is 
 an accessory obligation. Whereas, in the case of ordinary co- 
 debtors the situation is different. The vice in the consent of one 
 co-debtor is a defence which this co-debtor alone can take. It 
 is purely personal to him. The obligation of each of the other 
 co-debtors is a principal obligation, and its validity is unaffected 
 by the fact that the consent of a fello-vv debtor was vitiated. 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 419 
 
 (Baudry-Lacantinerie et Wahl, Contrats Aleatoires, etc. n. 948; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 2331; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1243; D. N, 
 O. C. art. 2036, n. 3.) 
 
 The Egyptian codes adopt this view and use somewhat different 
 terms in order to indicate the distinction. The co-debtor can 
 set up such exceptions as are "personal to himself," whereas the 
 surety "profits by the same exceptions as are open to the debtor, 
 save such as are essentially personal to the latter." (C. C. E. 
 112/168, 509/622. See Grandmoulin, Suretes, n. 80; Halton, 
 2, p. 222.) 
 
 Confusion. 
 
 The operation of confusion may create a personal exception. 
 The French Code says: When one of the co-debtors becomes 
 the sole heir of the creditor, or when the creditor becomes the sole 
 heir of one of the co-debtors, the confusion extinguishes the joint 
 and several debt only for the 'part and portion of the co-debtor or 
 of the creditor. (C. C. F. 1209.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code means to express the same rule more 
 shortly: lie can only set up confusion of the obligation in 
 respect of the share of that one of his co-debtors whose joint 
 liability has been extinguished by confusion. (C. C. E. 
 113/169.) One cannot combine in one's own person the antago- 
 nistic characters of creditor" and debtor. 
 
 Though the French article speaks only of the " sole heir," the 
 principle applies when the heir succeeds only to a share. In so 
 far as the debt, if it could be conceived of as still existing, would 
 be a debt which one of the co-debtors owed to himself, it is neces- 
 sarily extinguished. For example, John and William borrow 
 L. E. 9,000 from Thomas; John succeeds to Thomas as heir to 
 one-third of his estate. But for the principle of confusion he 
 could sue himself for one-third of L. E. 9,000. By the operation 
 of that principle the debt is extinguished to that extent. The 
 rule applias also when the same person becomes creditor and debtor 
 by the operation of a gift or of an assignment. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 2, n. 1241; Laurent, 17, n. 337.) 
 
 Compensation. 
 
 As regards the defence of compensation it might at first appear 
 that this was not a personal exception but one common to all the 
 co-debtors; for it is often said that compensation is a kind of 
 payment — compenser cest payer — and any one of the co-debtors 
 
 27 (2) 
 
420 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 may plead that the debt has been paid. But in this case it is not 
 true that compensation is equivalent to payment. There is a 
 special provision on the subject: One of several debtors liable 
 jointly and severally cannot set up a compensation to which one 
 of his co-debtors is entitled. (C. C. E. 113/169.) This article 
 must be read in connection with a later article: A co-debtor 
 jointly and severally liable with others cannot set up in compen- 
 sation that which is due to his co-debtors, excepting to the extent 
 of the share of the Utter in the liability. (C. C. E. 201/265.} 
 For instance, A, B and C are co-debtors to D for L. E. 900; 
 D then becomes a debtor to B for L. E. 900. If D sues C, C 
 can plead that L. E. 300 is paid by compensation with B. To 
 allow C to plead that the whole L. E. 900 was paid would be to 
 make B advance the L. E. 600 in the first place. It would also be 
 inconvenient to allow one co-debtor to raise a question which would 
 involve looking into accounts between the creditor and another 
 co-debtor beyond the share of such co-debtor. (Larombiere, 
 Oblig. art. 1294, n. 5.) 
 
 But the Egyptian Code allows the co-debtor to plead compen- 
 sation as to the share of the other co-debtor. And the Code of 
 Quebec is in the same sense. (C. C. Q. 1191.) The French 
 Code does not even give this right. (C. C. F. 1294; B.-L. et 
 Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1250; Planiol, 2, n. 766; Laurent, 17, n. 339; 
 Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 205; C. Cass', de Belgique, 13 juin 1872, 
 D. 74. 2. 128.) 
 
 Some French authorities resist this conclusion, but the terms 
 of the French article arc too clear for argument. (See, however, 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 41. text and note 19.) 
 
 Chose jugee. 
 
 As regards the plea of chose jugee there has been much con- 
 troversy. If an action is brought against one of the co-debtors, 
 in what cases can he plead that the question has been decided 
 against the creditor in a previous action against another of the 
 co-debtors? It is clear that he cannot do so when the ground upon 
 which the other co-debtor succeeded was a personal ground, such 
 as the minority of that co-debtor, or that the other co-debtor was 
 induced to enter into the contract by fraud. But when the ground 
 of the judgment was common to all the co-debtors, as, for instance, 
 if the defence was sustained that the obligation was for an un- 
 lawful cause, is this judgment res judicata as to the others? The 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 421 
 
 prevailing view in France is in favour of the affirmative, though 
 some writers dispute its soundness. The great reason in support 
 of the view taken by the French courts, and by most of the writers, 
 is that, seeing that the creditor can sup each of the co-debtors for 
 the whole debt, if he sues any one of them, all questions as to the 
 legal liability created by the obligation are put in issue, and 
 ho is in the same position as if he had sued them all together:. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1231; Cass, ler dec. 
 1885, D. 86. 1. 251; D. N. C. C. art. 1351, nos. 1435 seq.) 
 
 Upon the same principle it is held that when the joint and 
 several debtors are all sued together, and a judgment is given 
 against them, and one of them takes the case to appeal and succeeds 
 in getting the judgment reversed or modified, this enures to the 
 benefit of the other co-debtors, although they did not join in the 
 appeal. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 2, n. 1235; Caen, 5 mai 
 1894, D. 95. 2. 329; D. Rep. Appel Civil n. 585.) 
 
 Conversely, according to the French jurisprudence, if the 
 creditor has sued one of the co-debtors and has obtained a judg- 
 ment in his favour this judgment is opposable to the other co- 
 debtors. Char mi des codebiteurs solidaires doit etre considere 
 ■comme le contradkteur legitime du creancier et le representcmt 
 necessairt de ses eooblig.es. (Cass. 28 dec. 1881, D. 82. 1. 377; 
 Cass. 25 mars 1902, D. 1905. 1. 325.) 
 
 But there are three qualifications to be made. 
 The creditor cannot enforce his judgment against the co-debtors 
 who were not parties to the action: (1) If they prove that there 
 was collusion betweeen the creditor and the debtor who was sued; 
 (2) if the co-debtor against whom the creditor seeks to oppose 
 the judgment has an exception personal to himself which he can 
 oppose to the creditor; and (3) if the debtor who was sued negli- 
 gently failed to plead an exception, such as prescription, which 
 was common to all co-debtors. 
 
 These cannot be deprived by the negligence of their co-debtor 
 of a defence available in favour of all of them. (See Req. 25 nov. 
 1903, S. 1906. 1. 345, and the note; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 208; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1233.) It is submitted that the Egyptian law 
 is the same as to this matter, and that this is implied in C. C. E. 
 110/166. Against this opinion, it may be urged that by the terms 
 of the Egyptian Code the co-debtors are reciprocal mandataries 
 only "for performance." There is no mandate to represent each 
 other judicially. (De Hults, Rep. Obligations, n. 128/ And 
 in one case the Mixed Court of Appeal held: Les effets de In 
 
422 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 solidwite nont pas pour consequence de rendre line decision de 
 justice, obtenue contre Vun des co-debiteurs solidaires, executoire 
 contre celui au regard duquel la decision ne renferme aucune con- 
 damnation on disposition quelconque. (C. A. Alex. 28 dec. 
 1904, B. L. J. XVII, 50.) 
 
 Release. 
 
 The Egyptian Code has only one article upon this subject, and 
 it leaves many questions unsettled. The code says of a joint and 
 several debtor: Re may not set up a release of the debt for more 
 than the share of that one of his co-debtors to whom the release 
 has been granted, unless the release be absolute, which shall not be 
 presumed. (C. C. E. 114/170.) 
 
 This article is dealing with a release of the debt, but it is 
 desirable, before speaking of that subject, to discuss the case of 
 release from the joint and several liability; — remise de la solidarity 
 — as to which the Egyptian Code is quite silent. 
 
 The creditor may, if he likes, agree that a certain co-debtor,, 
 instead of being liable for the whole debt shall be liable only for 
 his share. Such a form of release given to one of the co-debtors 
 does not affect the joint and several liability of the other debtors. 
 
 The solidarity was created primarily in the interest of the 
 creditor, and, therefore, he is entitled to renounce it as against one 
 of the debtors. But, as will be shown later, the creditor cannot 
 in this way increase the burden of another co-debtor. There is, 
 of course, nothing to prevent the creditor if he chooses from giving 
 a release to one of the debtors by which he agrees to release themt 
 all from the joint and several liability without releasing them 
 from the debt. 
 
 This is called absolute release of solidarity as distinguished 
 from the relative release in favour of one of the debtors. 
 
 But such an absolute renunciation of the solidarity hardly 
 occurs in practice; and is not mentioned by any of the codes. 
 There can be no difficulty about it, for unless the creditor declares 
 in very clear language that this is his intention it will not be 
 presumed . 
 
 But the relative release is important and common, and it raises 
 somewhat difficult questions. Such a relative release may be 
 express or it may be tacit, and it is, as a matter of fact, very 
 frequently tacit. The French Code states a number of facts from 
 which such a renunciation will be implied. 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 423 
 
 (1) If the creditor gives a discharge to one of the debtors in 
 which he says that it is in respect of his share— pour sa part— 
 this is held to imply that he releases him from the solidarity. 
 The fact that the creditor has taken payment from one of th,e. 
 co-debtors of his equal share of the amount of the debt and has 
 given him a receipt for it, is not a release from the solidarity.. 
 The creditor may quite well intend to reserve his right of falling 
 back upon this debtor if he cannot get payment from the other 
 debtors. But if he distinctly states in the receipt that he takes 
 the money as the share or portion of the debt which this debtor 
 owes to him, it is quite reasonable to say, as the French Code 
 does, that this is a release from the solidarity. If he wants to 
 make it clear that this is not the case he must say in the receipt 
 that he reserves his rights, by using some such expression asi sans 
 prejudice de la solidmite or sans prejudice de mes droits. These 
 are the solutions of the Roman law and of the old French law 
 which are preserved in the French Code. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 277 ; 
 C. C. F. 1211; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1283; Laurent, 17, n. 348.) 
 There can be no doubt the Egyptian law is the same. The Egyp- 
 tian Code says merely: A release granted to one of several 
 debtors jointly and severally liable is deemed to have been granted 
 for his share and extinguishes the liability as regards such share 
 only. (C. C. E. 182/245. See De Hults, Rep. vo. Obligations, 
 n. 99, seq.) 
 
 (2) If the creditor makes a demand for payment against one 
 of the co-debtors claiming a certain sum and alleging that it is 
 pour sa part, one might be inclined to suppose that this form of 
 demand was equivalent to a renunciation by the creditor. 
 
 But, according to the French law, the mere claim in this form 
 is not enough, because the renunciation needs to be accepted 
 before it is binding upon the creditor. If the creditor makes a 
 demand against one of the debtors "for his share," and the debtor 
 offers to pay it, there is a contract, and it will be too late for the 
 creditor to claim any more from that debtor. And if the creditor 
 obtains a judgment in the action against the debtor he will like- 
 wise be bound by it. (C.C.F.1211; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1284; 
 Larombiere, art. 1211, nos. 7, 9, and 10; Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 54.) 
 
 No doubt the Egyptian law is the same as to these points also. 
 
 (3) The creditor, who receives from one of the co-debtors his 
 
 share of arrears or interest of the debt and gives a receipt stating 
 
 that it is for the share of this debtor, is held to renounce the 
 
424 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 solidarity as regards past arrears or interest. But the discharge 
 does not in any way affect the liability of this debtor as regards 
 the capita] of the debt, or as regards future interest, unless the 
 creditor has gone on for ten consecutive years to receive payment 
 of interest in this way from one of the co-debtors. 
 
 In that case he is considered to have shown his intention not 
 to claim from this debtor more than his proportionate share of the 
 interest in any future year. 
 
 This period of ten years stated in the French Code is neces- 
 sarily somewhat arbitrary, and as the Egyptian Code has no 
 similar article the Egyptian courts would not be bound to insist 
 upon payments for ten years. They are entitled to consider in 
 each case upon the particular facts whether the conduct of the 
 creditor sufficiently shows his intention to release the debtor from 
 the solidarity. But, in judging of this question, it is natural 
 that the Egyptian courts should look to the French Code as a 
 guide. (C. C. F. 1211, 1212; B.-L. et Barde, 2, nos. 1285, 
 1286; Aubry et I\au, 5th ed. 4, p. 55.) 
 
 What is the effect of the release from the solidarity if 
 one of the co-debtors becomes insolvent? 
 
 This is a much disputed question. One of the principal objects 
 of joint and several liability, from the point of view of the 
 creditor, is that he can secure full payment of his debt if the, 
 co-debtors have got the money among them. The fact that one 
 of them can pay nothing, or can pay only the half of his share, 
 has the effect of throwing a larger burden upon the others. If 
 of three co-debtors two could pay nothing at all the third co-debtor 
 would still be liable for the whole amount. For the law declares 
 the liability of such of them as are insolvent shall be divided 
 among those who arc *ohe?it. (C . C. E. 115 17-1; C. C. F. 
 1214.) 
 
 As anion," the co-debtors themselves, if one of them is insolvent, 
 the sum which he cannot pay to the creditor is divided among the 
 other debtors according to their shares. 
 
 Now, suppose the creditor releases one of the co-debtors from 
 the solidarity, and, afterwards, one of the other co-debtors be- 
 comes insolvent, who is to bear the loss causxl by this insolvency? 
 Suppose, for example, the creditor has lent L. E. 9,000 to Zaki, 
 Ahmed and Mohammed jointlv and severally. He receives 
 L. E. t'3.000 from Zaki and gives him a receipt specifying that 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVKEAL OBLIGATIONS. 425 
 
 it is for his share and without, reserving any rights. The effect 
 of (his is that Zaki is released from the joint and several Liability. 
 If, afterwards, Ahmed becomes insolvent, and his estate can pay 
 only 50 piastres in the pound, there i< a lo3S of L. E. 1.000 which 
 has to be borne by somebody . 
 
 Is it to be borne by the creditor or by Mohammed? If Zaki 
 had not been released from the solidarity by the creditor, this loss 
 of L. E. 1,500 caused by the insolvency of Ahmed would have 
 been divided between Zaki and Mohammed. And, assuming for 
 (he sake of simplicity, that the shares were equal, Zaki would have 
 had to pay L. E. 750 and Mohammed would have had to pay also 
 L. E. 750. But if the release given by the creditor' to Zaki is to 
 be considered as relieving him of this liability caused by the 
 insolvency of Ahmed, and if Mohammed has to pay the whole 
 sum of L. E. 1,500, the release given by the creditor to Zaki will 
 have caused a dead loss to Mohammed of L. E. 750. This result 
 is inadmissible. 
 
 As among the co-debtors themselves the joint and several 
 liability is for their mutual protection. They know, when they 
 become jointly and severally bound, that if one of them has to 
 pay to the creditor more than his share of the debt, he will have 
 a right of recourse against his fellow debtors. In entering into 
 the obligation they relied upon the solvency of each other. It 
 would be contrary to the understanding of the parties and to 
 equity to allow the creditor by a contract with one of the co-debtors 
 to cause a prejudice to the others. If we admit this, the conclu- 
 sion must bo either: (1) that the loss of L. E. 750 must fall upon 
 the creditor himself, as it would not have arisen but for his having 
 released Zaki; or (2) that in spite of the creditor having released 
 Zaki, Mohammed will have a recourse against Zaki for L. E. 750, 
 and further, that if Mohammed were himself insolvent the creditor, 
 in spite of the release, could sue Zaki for the whole debt. 
 The French doctrine is- divided upon this point. 
 According to Pothier and to some more modern writers it is 
 the creditor who must bear the loss. 
 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 275, at 4; Larombiero, art. 1215, n. 2; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1215, n. 2.) 
 
 Applying the rule of Pothier to our illustration, the result 
 would be that the creditor could sue Mohammed for L. E. 3,750, 
 which, with the L. E. 3,000 he has got from Zaki, and the L. E. 
 1,500 he has got from Ahmed's insolvent estate, will make L. E. 
 8,250, leaving the creditor to bear the loss of L. E. 750. 
 
426 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 This solution has been expressly adopted by the Civil Code of 
 Quebec. (C. C. Q. 1119.) The shares of those who are insol- 
 vent are made up by contribution by all the other co-debtors 
 except the one discharged, whose part in the contribution is borne 
 by the creditor. 
 
 But, unfortunately, the language of the French Code and of 
 the Egyptian Code will not bear this interpretation. 
 
 The French Code says: Dans les cas ou le creancier a renonce 
 a V action solidaire etnvers Vim des debiteurs, si Vun ou plusieurs 
 des autres codebiteurs deviennent insohables, la portion des in- 
 solvable* sera contributoirement repartie entre tous les debiteurs, 
 meme entre ceux precedemment decharges de la solidarite par 
 le creancier. (C. C. F. 1215.) 
 
 And the Egyptian Code says that when a co-debtor has been 
 released from his share of the debt the rest of the debtors can 
 recover from him only his contribution to the share of those of 
 them, if any, who are insolvent. (C. C. E. 183/246.) In spite 
 of the release, the creditor can still fall back on the co-debtor for 
 his share of this liability. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1262; Auhry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 52, note 43; Laurent, 17, n. 363; Req. 7 
 juin 1882, S. 82. 1. 321, Journal du Palais, 82, p. 774, D. 82. 
 1. 441.) The French Code is speaking of the case of release from 
 the solidarity, and the Egyptian Code of the case of release of his 
 share. But by the argument a fortiori, we may say that if the 
 co-debtor remains liable to contribute when he has been released 
 from the debt it must be so, still more clearly, when he has beeai 
 released merely from the solidarity. It is a general principle of 
 interpretation that renunciations are to be interpreted restric- 
 tively . 
 
 The presumption is always against a man giving up a right. 
 If therefore a creditor merely releases his debtor from the soli- 
 darity, and says nothing of what is to happen in case of the future 
 insolvency of one of the other debtors, the presumption is that he 
 does not intend the release to apply to this liability. (See De 
 Hults, Rep. Obligations, n. 103.) 
 
 The objection is sometimes made that if this is the case the 
 release from the solidarity does not produce any effect at all. But 
 this is not true; the debtor Avho is released from the solidarity 
 gains, at any rate, this advantage, that the creditor cannot pick 
 him out from among the debtors and sue him in the first place 
 for the whole debt. He can at the worst only sue him for his 
 share, and the probability is that if one of the debtors is solvent 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. 427 
 
 the creditor will begin by suing this solvent debtor for the whole 
 debt. (Pond. Frmig. Oblig. n. 513; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1262. See the note by M. Aubry to Req. 7 juin 1882, D. 
 82. 1. 441.) 
 
 Is the effect of a release from the solidarity to oblige the 
 creditor to deduct the share of the debtor released? 
 
 This also is a controversial question in the French law. The 
 language of the French Code seems clearly in favour of the 
 affirmative. 
 
 he creancier qui consent a la division de la dette a Vegard de 
 Vun des codebiteurs conserve son action solidmre contre les autres, 
 mais sous la deduction de la part du debiteur qu'il a decharge de 
 la solidarite. (C. C. F. 1210.) 
 
 But this article is altogether unreasonable. If the creditor 
 merely wishes to release the debtor from the solidarity why should 
 he not be allowed to do so without at the same time releasing him 
 from his share of the debt? The release from the solidarity does 
 not prejudice the other debtors. Each of them was always liable 
 to be sued for the whole debt, and if one of them paid it he had 
 a recourse against the others for their shares. It is admitted that 
 the creditor cannot deprive them of this right of recourse, but 
 there does not seem any reason why he cannot agree if he chooses 
 to hold one of the debtors liable only for his share and not for the 
 whole debt. This is so obvious that some French authors argue 
 that we cannot take C. C. F. 1210 literally. We must understand 
 it to mean that it is only when the creditor has received payment 
 of a debtor's share, or has chosen to release him from it without' 
 payment, and thus make him a present of it, that he must deduct 
 this share from his claim when he sues the other co-debtors. 
 (Larombiere, art. 1210, n. 7; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 52.) 
 But however desirable this conclusion may be, it is directly in the 
 teeth of C. C. F. 1210. (Demolombe, 26, n. 463, and n. 464; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1281.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code, however, has no corresponding article, and 
 we ought accordingly to adopt the more natural and logical view 
 that a creditor who has released a debtor from the solidarity does 
 not thereby abandon his right to sue the other debtors for the 
 whole amount of the debt. This is the solution adopted by the 
 Code of Quebec and by the Italian Code. (C. C. Q. 1114; C. C. 
 Ital. 1195.) We must, however, not forget that the debtor thus 
 
428 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 released from the solidarity remains liable in recourse for the 
 amount of his share to the co-debtor who has been called upon to 
 pay the debt. And the debtor thus released also remains liable 
 to pay his share of the loss which arises from the insolvency of 
 one of the other debtors. 
 
 Release of the debt. 
 
 We have now considered the effects of the release from the 
 solidarity, and it remains to speak of the release of the debt itself. 
 
 Unfortunately, the Egyptian Code is not very satisfactory on 
 this subject. 
 
 Suppose Zaki, Ahmed and Mohammed owe L. E. 9,000 jointly 
 and severally. The creditor gives to Zaki a release in general 
 terms. 
 
 Under the Egyptian Code this is taken to mean that he releases 
 Zaki from his share. The release does not affect the liability of 
 Ahmed and Mohammed, except that, from the claim against them, 
 the creditor must deduct Zaki's share which has been paid or 
 released without payment. Zaki, in spite of the release remains 
 liable, as we have seen, for his share of the loss caused by the 
 insolvency of Ahmed or Mohammed. (C. C. E. 114/170, 182, 
 183/245, 246.) 
 
 The release here, as in the previous case, may be tacit; it 
 requires acceptance and may be proved by witnesses. The French 
 Code has the very unreasonable rule that a release in general terms 
 given to one of the co-debtors has the effect of liberating them all 
 unless the creditor in the release has expressly reserved his rights. 
 (C. C. F. 1285^ But the Egyptian Code, fortunately, has no 
 such article. (See infra, p. 497.) 
 
 Alleged imperfect solidarity. 
 
 Some French writers contend that the provisions of the code 
 as to joint and several liability apply in full only to the joint and 
 several liability which is created by agreement. They call this 
 xnlidaritc parfaite. The position of persons declared by law to 
 be jointly and severally liable apart from agreement is, according 
 to these writers, not quite the same. They describe their position 
 as sniid-arite imparfmte. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 30/ 
 
 The difference between the two cases arises, it is said, from the 
 fact that when there is perfect solidarity the debtors are con- 
 sidered as mandataries one for the other, whereas when the soli- 
 
JOINT AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLIGATIONS. t29 
 
 darity is created by the law we cannot say that they are reciprocal 
 mandataries. It is conceivable that three persons should be held 
 jointly and severally liable for a delict or a quasi-delict, although 
 they did not know each other and had made no agreement. How 
 can we say in such a case that there is anything like a mandate? 
 But, as Planiol says, the answer to this seems to be that the 
 solidarity is created by the law, not because the law presumes the 
 existence of a mandate, but because the debtors have such a 
 common interest that they are in a similar position to joint man- 
 dataries. (2, n. 778.) This distinction between perfect soli- 
 darity and imperfect solidarity does not seem to be gaining ground 
 in France, and has been rejected by the jurisprudence. (Paris. 
 28 mai 1900, D. 1902. 2. 453. See Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 210. 
 There would be no excuse for introducing the theory into Egypt, 
 because the Egyptian Code declares expressly that the debtors 
 are reciprocal mandataries, and makes no distinction between the 
 case when the joint and several liability arises from agreement 
 and the cases in which it arises from the law. (C. C. E. 108/162. 
 
 Two debtors may be liable each for the whole debt 
 without any solidarity. 
 
 It is quite possible for each of the co-defendants to be liable 
 for the whole debt to the plaintiff but upon two distinct and 
 separate titles, in which case there will be no solidarity. (C. A. 
 Alex. 29 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII," 453; C. A. Alex. 15 
 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 156.) 
 
 Effects of joint and several liability as among the 
 co-debtors themselves. 
 
 It is only in regard to the creditor that each of the debtors i& 
 bound to pay the whole debt. As among themselves, each is liable 
 only for his share, and, if he is compelled by the creditor to pay 
 more than his share, he has a recourse against the others for the 
 excess. In paying the whole debt, or anything in excess of his 
 share, he gets a right of recourse against each of the others for 
 their shares. (C. C. E. 115/171.) 
 
 As among the co-debtors themselves, the obligation is not joint 
 and several, but only joint; each is liable only for his own share 
 and portion. What this share is depends on the agreement be- 
 tween them if the solidarity arises from contract, or on their 
 respective culpability if it arises from a wrong. The presumption 
 
430 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 is that the co-debtors arc liable in equal shares, but this presump- 
 tion can be rebutted. (See Liege, 3 mars 1886, D. 88. 2. 71.) 
 
 There would be a useless circuity of actions if the co-debtor 
 who had paid the whole debt could sue a co-debtor for the whole 
 debt minus the share which the plaintiff had paid, and leave him 
 in his turn to sue another co-debtor for the whole debt minus his 
 share. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 281, al. 2.) But a co-debtor who 
 has paid the whole debt may, in one case, have a claim against a 
 co-debtor for more than an equal share of the debt, though the 
 liability of the co-debtors was originally equal. 
 
 This is when one of the co-debtors is insolvent. For example, 
 A, B and C are joint and several debtors to D for L. E. 900. 
 D sues A for the whole debt, and A pays it; B becomes insolvent 
 and can pay nothing; A has a recourse against C for L. E. 300, 
 his equal share of the debt, plus L. E. 150, the half of B's share. 
 (C. C. E. 115/171.) As already said, however, it is perfectly 
 possible that, as among themselves, the liability is unequal, and 
 it may be that the debt was contracted solely for one of them. 
 (C. C. F. 1216; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1272; Lyon, 6 fevr. 1890, 
 D. 91. 2. 377.) 
 
 Thus, in the case of a bill of exchange, the acceptor of the bill 
 is, as a rule, the principal debtor, and the drawer and endorser 
 are accessory debtors. 
 
 In such a case if the acceptor meets the bill when it is due he 
 has no recourse at all against the drawer and the endorser. As 
 among themselves, he is the only debtor and they are his sureties. 
 As against the holder of the bill they are all principal debtors. 
 (Thaller,' Traite Elemmtaire de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. 
 n. 1527.^1 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 431 
 
 CHAPTER XXIII. 
 
 DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 This difficult subject is treated of, by no means very adequately, 
 in tbe French Code in arts. 1217—1225. It is dismissed sum- 
 marily in a single article in the Egyptian Code: When the per- 
 formance of cm obligation cannot, whether in the nature of things 
 or in view of the purpose of the obligation, be divided, each of the 
 debtors is liable for the whole, subject to his right of recourse 
 against his co-debtors. (C. C. E. 116/172.) 
 
 Both in [the Eoman and in the French law this has always 
 been considered as one of the most obscure parts of the law. It 
 was dealt with at great length and with much acuteness by the 
 great French commentator Dumoulin, and Pothier does not do 
 much more than condense Dumoulin's views on the subject, while 
 the Code Napoleon in its turn condenses the doctrine of Pothier. 
 (Laurent, 17, n. 503.) Subsequent French writers have done 
 a good deal to place the matter in a clearer light. Toullier went 
 so far as to express the hope that the doctrine of indivisibility, 
 might some day be banished from the code as a piece of useless 
 theory. (6, n. 798.) But Eodiere rightly says that indivisible 
 obligations inevitably occur, and it is useless for the law to try to 
 change that which is founded in the very nature of things. {De 
 la Solidarite et de I'lndivisibilite, n. 389.) Indivisible obliga- 
 tions must be taken account of in every system of law. For 
 example, in the English law, Sir F. Pollock says: "A' contract 
 which can be fulfilled only as a whole, so that failure in any part 
 is failure in the whole, is said to be entire. A contract of which 
 the performance can be separated so that failure in one part affects 
 the parties' rights as to that part only is said to be divisible." 
 (Pollock on Contracts, 8th ed. p. 275.) And there are many 
 English cases in which the doctrine of an entire or indivisible 
 contract is elaborated. (See e.g., Cutter v. Powell, 1795, 3 E. E. 
 185, 2 Smith's Leading Cases, 1 : Appleby v. Meyers, 1867, L. E. 
 2 C. P. 651, 36 L. J. C. P. 331; Sumpter v. Hedges, 1898, 1 
 
432 THE LAW OF OMLIGATIONS. 
 
 Q. B. 673, 07 L. J. Q. B. 545; Format/ & Co. v. Ship Liddes- 
 dale, 1900, A. C. 190, 69 L. J. P. C. 44.) 
 
 Indivisibility always means the same thing, viz., that it is 
 impossible for the debtor to perform his obligation in part; he 
 must perform it altogether or not at all. This impossibility may 
 arise in either of two ways: (1) from the nature of things; or (2) 
 from the intention of the parties. 
 
 (1) Obligations indivisible by nature. 
 
 In the first case, the object of the obligation is by its nature 
 not susceptible of division either materially or intellectually. 
 
 Conversely, when the object of the obligation is a thing which 
 in its delivery or performance is susceptible of division, either 
 materially or intellectually, the obligation is divisible. For 
 instance, a debtor who is bound to pay a sum of money, such as 
 L. E. 300, can fulfil his obligation in part if ho pays L. E. 100, 
 and a person who sells a horse can perform his obligation in part 
 if he gives the buyer a half -share in the horse. In this last case, 
 it is true, the division cannot be material, for a section of tho 
 horse would be of no value, but an intellectual division is per- 
 fectly possible and practical. Two persons may be joint-owners 
 of a horse as of other kinds of property. 
 
 It is true that the law does not allow the debtor in an obligation 
 to divide the performance in this way. He must perform the 
 obligation as if it were indivisible. A debtor cannot eomp 1 his 
 creditor to receive payment of his debt in part. (C. C. E. 
 168/231: infra, p. 451.) But this is not because the debt 
 is naturally indivisible. On the contrary, it is clearly 
 divisible. The reason why performance cannot be divided is be- 
 en us" the parties to the contract intended an entire performance. 
 A divisible obligation must b\ perfonwed between the creditor. 
 and the debtor as if it were indivisible. (C. C. F. 1220; C. C. Q. 
 1122.) As between the creditor and the debtor, therefore, there 
 is no importance in knowing whether an obligation is divisible 
 or indivisible. But the distinction becomes important when either 
 the creditor or the debtor dies and is succeeded by several heirs. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1312.) In this caso 
 if the debt is divisible the heirs of the debtor will be liable only 
 in proportion to their shares in the succession. (See Cass. 17 dec. 
 1907, D. 1908. 1. 140; Req. 13 janv. 1908, D. 1909. 1. 179.) 
 
 And, in like manner, the heirs of the creditor will be entitled 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 433 
 
 to claim each of them only his share, corresponding to his share 
 in the creditor's succession. One who is heir of the debtor to the 
 extent of two-thirds will be liable for two-thirds of the debt, one 
 who is heir of the creditor to the extent of two-thirds will be 
 entitled to claim two-thirds of the debt, and so forth. (See 
 C. C. F. 1220; C. C. Q. 1122.) 
 
 There are even here certain cases which are declared by the 
 code to be exceptions. (C. C. F. 1221; C. C. Q. 1123.) These 
 will be explained later, but the rule is that a divisible obligation 
 divides among the heirs either actively or passively. On the 
 other hand, when the obligation is indivisible by nature no such 
 division among the heirs of the creditor or the heirs of the debtor 
 is conceivable. The obligation must be performed altogether or 
 it must fail altogether. It is impossible to perform one-third of 
 it, or to divide the performance in any way. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 76.) 
 
 To take some familiar examples: If A binds himself to grant 
 a right of way to B, and A dies before the servitude has been 
 created, leaving three heirs, and B sues one of the heirs, this heir 
 cannot plead that he is liable only to the extent of one-third, and 
 that he is willing to grant the servitude to this extent. A right: 
 of way must exist or not exist as a whole. 
 
 The extent of the use may, of course, vary. A man may use a 
 road every day, or only once a week, and he might, conceivably, 
 have the right to use it only once a week, but that is quite a 
 different thing from a division of the right itself. 
 
 It is inconceivable that a man should have half a right of way 
 or a quarter of a right of way. He must have the whole of a right 
 of way whatever its extent may be. (Demolombe, 26, n. 524; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 77; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1314. 
 Cf. Cass. 6 fevr. 1872, D. 72. 1. 101.) Similarly, where a debtor 
 is bound to communicate a title, or to deliver a specific thing, or 
 to render an account, or to perform a juridical act such as enter- 
 ing an appeal, or to register a hypothec, part-performance of such 
 an obligation is inconceivable. (D. Rep. Oblig. n. 1513.) In 
 like manner, an obligation by two dramatic authors to produce 
 an opera by a certain date is naturally indivisible. (Paris, 13 
 nov. 1888, D. 90. 2. 238.) In such cases as those enumerated 
 the obligation may be described as naturally or necessarily indivi- 
 sible, or, to use Pothier's language, the indivisibility is absolute. 
 
 In principle, actions are likewise divisible or indivisible accord- 
 ing to the nature of the object sued for. But this belongs to 
 
 W.— VOL. II. 2° 
 
434 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the law of procedure. (Cass. 30 dec. 1908, et lor mars 1911, 
 D. 1913. 1. 89; Cass. 29 avril 1895, D. 95. 1. 454.) 
 
 (2) Obligations indivisible by agreement. 
 
 The second group of indivisible obligations consists of those in 
 which the indivisibility does not arise from the nature of things; 
 for it would be quite possible to perform the obligation in part, 
 but, nevertheless, the obligation is indivisible, because the parties 
 contemplated and intended that it should be performed as a whole 
 and should not be divided. 
 
 Here the indivisibility may bo described as conventional. For 
 instance, a builder contracts to build a house, a sculptor to make 
 a statue, a painter to paint a picture. In such cases, and many 
 others, where what is contemplated is the production of an opus 
 or completed work, it may very well be that the intention of the 
 parties was that nothing was to be paid unless the work was 
 completed. The man who contracts to pay L. E. 500 or to 
 deliver 500 bushels of wheat, and pays L. E. 250 or delivers 250 
 bushels, makes a prestation of definite value, but the heir of a 
 sculptor would not be entitled to say, " my ancestor did one-third 
 of the statue, I am entitled to one-third of the price." An un- 
 finished statue or picture has, very probably, no value at all, 
 and the completion of the work was, or may well have been, con- 
 templated as a condition precedent to the right to sue. And, 
 although half a house may be of some value, yet the obligation to 
 build a house is an indivisible obligation if it was so intended by 
 the parties. (Demolombe, 26, n. 525; Cass. 23 juin 1851, D. 
 51. 1. 165; Rodiere, De la Solidarite et de Vlndwisibilite, n. 345.) 
 It is a question of intention. 
 
 The two kinds of indivisibility which have been discussed are 
 those which Dumoulin describes as: (1) the case where the in- 
 divisibility is contractu — an expression not very happily chosen 
 by him to denote the case of the indivisibility of the nature of the 
 object— and (2) the case where the indivisibility is obligatione, 
 that is, where it might be performed in part but the parties have 
 shown their intention that it is to be performed as a whole,. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. nos. 291, 292.) 
 
 It is better to distinguish these two kinds of indivisibility as 
 natural and conventional. 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 435 
 
 English law as to this. 
 
 The English law offers interesting analogies. The rule, for 
 example, in building contracts is that if payment was to be made 
 upon the completion of the work, and the builder fails to complete, 
 he cannot claim the contract price. Nor can he charge for the 
 value of the work done unless there has been some ratification by 
 the other party which excuses him from completing the work. 
 (Sumpter v. Hedges, 1898, 1 Q. B. 673, 67 L. J. Q. B. 545. 
 See Leake, Contracts, 6th ed. p. 38.) 
 
 Indivisibility on one side only. 
 
 Dumoulin, and Pothier following him, give a third case of 
 indivisibility, which they describe as indivisibility merely as 
 regards performance-— solutione tantum. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 294.) 
 The thing due is here perfectly divisible, but the parties have 
 agreed that it shall be performed as a whole. What distinguishes 
 this case from the case of conventional indivisibility is that the 
 parties do not intend the obligation to be indivisible both actively 
 and passively. If the creditor dies, and is succeeded by several 
 heirs, each of these heirs cannot insist upon the whole performance. 
 
 On the other hand, if the debtor dies and is succeeded by several 
 heirs, one of these heirs, though not always each of them, may be 
 called upon to pay the whole debt. They are in fact cases of 
 conventional indivisibility on one side only. The French Code 
 does not regard these cases as examples of genuine indivisibility, 
 but as cases in which an obligation naturally divisible must, for 
 certain special reasons, be performed as if it were indivisible. 
 The three exceptional cases dealt with in article 1221 of the 
 French Code are the following: — 
 
 (1) When the object of the obligation is a certain specific thing 
 of which one of the heirs is in possession. In this case, where 
 the debtor has left several heirs that one of them who possesses the 
 thing due may be sued to deliver it. For example, John dies 
 leaving three heirs. In the partition of his succession, a picture 
 which was in his house falls to the share of William, one of these 
 heirs. It turns out afterwards that the picture did- not belong 
 to John at all, but had been left with him as a deposit. Its 
 owner is entitled to sue William to deliver it. Under the old 
 law a more common case was when the debtor had sold a specificl 
 thing, but had not delivered it before his death. In this case 
 
 28 '2] 
 
436 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the buyer could compel the heir into whose share it had fallen to 
 deliver it. Under the modern law he can do so upon a simpler 
 ground, viz., that the specific thing became his property at the 
 time of the agreement, and that he can therefore revindicate it 
 from the holder. 
 
 The holder will have a recourse against his co-heirs, if in the 
 deed of partition he was not charged with the entire payment of 
 this debt. (C. C. F. 1221; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1323, b.; Aubry et Rau,. 5th ed. 4, p. 87; Laurent, 17, n. 409.) 
 
 (2) When one only of the heirs of the debtor is charged by 
 the title with the performance of the obligation. For instance, 
 John leaves his estate equally to William and Thomas, but he 
 charges Thomas to pay a debt of L'. E. 10,000 to Henry. This 
 case presents no difficulty; Thomas can be sued for the whole 
 debt, saving his recourse against William, unless John intended 
 that Thomas was to bear this burden without any recourse as a 
 charge upon his share. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 313; Laurent, 17, 
 n. 416; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 89; B.-L. et Barde, 1, 
 n. 222. See Civ. 16 fevr. 1858, D. 58. 1. 128.) 
 
 (3) When it results either from the nature of the contract, or 
 of the thing which is the object of it, or from the end proposed by 
 it, that the intention of the contracting parties was that the 
 obligation should not be performed in part. (C. A. Alex. 18 
 juin 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 447.) This differs from the two 
 preceding cases in this respect, that each of the co-heirs may be 
 sued for the whole thing due. On the side of the debtor the 
 obligation is indivisible. But the heir who pays the whole will 
 have a recourse against his co-heirs for what he has paid in excess 
 of his share. 
 
 The cases contemplated in (3) are such as these:— The debtor 
 has promised a sum of money to the creditor to enable him to 
 meet a bill which is due on a certain date, or to exercise a right 
 of redemption. 
 
 Nothing is more divisible as a rule than money, and in the case 
 of an ordinary money-debt it would be natural that each of thie 
 heirs of the debtor should be liable only for his share. But in 
 this case the whole sum was required for a particular object which 
 was specified. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1327, b.; Laurent, 17, 
 n. 41.8; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 90.) 
 
 But there are many other cases in which the intention of the 
 parties clearly is that the obligation shall be performed as a whole, 
 although there is no intention to give to each of the heirs of the 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 437 
 
 creditor a right to exact the whole of what was due to his ancestor. 
 This is so when the .object of a contract of sale is something which 
 was to be delivered as a whole. For example, if a suite of furniture 
 is bought, it may easily appear that the intention was that the 
 whole suite should be delivered as described, and if the seller 
 substitutes certain other pieces for those which belonged to the 
 suite the buyer can refuse to take delivery. In such a case if the 
 seller dies, each of his heirs could be sued fo,r delivery of the; 
 suite. 
 
 But if the buyer died each of his heirs would not be liable for 
 the whole of the price. (See Tobey Furniture Co. v. Macmmter, 
 1902, R. J.Q. 12K.B.34.) 
 
 The same article of the French Code which gives these three 
 cases in which an obligation is indivisible as regards the heirs of 
 the debtor only, also mentions two other cases: — 
 
 (1) The hypothecary debt; and (2) an alternative obligation 
 to pay one of two things of which one is indivisible and the other 
 is not when the creditor has the choice. (C. C. F. 1221.) But 
 these are not genuine exceptions. 
 
 (1) In the -case of a debt secured by a hypothec the debt itself 
 is divided among the heirs of the debtor. 
 
 It is true that the heir who possesses the immoveable hypothe- 
 cated may be sued for the whole debt. 
 
 But as to this, he is merely in the position of any third-party 
 holder. He can escape his liability, if he chooses, by paying his 
 share and by surrendering the immoveable. (Planiol, 2, n. 721; 
 Laurent, 17, nos. 407, 413; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1322, a.) 
 
 (2) In the case of the alternative obligation all that is meant 
 is that the heirs of the debtor cannct, under the pretext that one 
 of the alternative prestations is divisible, prevent the creditor 
 from exercising his contractual right to choose the prestation 
 which is indivisible. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 88; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 2, n. 1324, c.) 
 
 As the Egyptian Code is silent as to these cases we are not 
 embarrassed by the inexactitude of the French Code on these 
 points. 
 
 The effects of indivisibility. 
 
 As previously explained, indivisibility makes no difference as 
 between the creditor and the debtor themselves, when there is only 
 one creditor and one debtor. In that case, every obligation may 
 
438 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 be said to be indivisible, because the debtor cannot insist upon 
 making a partial payment. 
 
 It is when there are several debtors or several creditor- that it 
 becomes important to distinguish between a divisible and an in- 
 divisible debt, and it is generally, though not always, the death of 
 one. of the parties, and his being succeeded by several heirs, which 
 raises the question of indivisibility. 
 
 The nature and extent of the heir's liability for the debt of his 
 ancestor is a part of the law of succession, and is governed in 
 Egypt by the personal law of the deceased. (C. C. E. 54/77.) 
 The rules of the Mohammedan law are very different from those 
 of the French law. (See C. A. Alex. 14 fevr. 1900, B. L. J. 
 XII, 130.) 
 
 What follows is a statement of the French law. 
 
 When the obligation is divisible, and the debtor dies, his person 
 is, as it were, broken up into as many fractions as there are heirs. 
 Each heir is liable only for his share, and is not obliged to take 
 the risk of the dishonesty or insolvency of his co-heirs. (C. C. F. 
 870; Aubry et Kau, 5th ed. 9, p. 377.) 
 
 It might seem fair enough that each heir should be liable at 
 least up to the value of what he has received, but the French law 
 does not say so. 
 
 The creditor has certain ways by which he may protect himself: 
 
 (1) He may before the partition execute a seizure on the whole 
 or any part of the property of the de cujus. (Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 9, p. 379, note 8; B.-L. et Wahl, Successions, 3rd ed. 3, n. 
 3044.) 
 
 (2) He may claim that the property falling to the heir be 
 kept separate from the heir's other property. This is what is 
 known as la separation des patrimoines . 
 
 When it has been granted, it gives to the creditor a preference 
 over the property coming from the succession for payment of the 
 debt of the ancestor. The heir's share does not become available 
 for his own creditors until the debts of the ancestor have been 
 paid. (C. C. F. 878; Pothier, Oblig. n. 309; Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 10, p. 59; D. N. C. C. art. 878, nos. 185, seq. ; Cass. l 29 janv. 
 1900, D. 1900. 1. 269.) 
 
 But the general principle is that debts are divided among the 
 heirs in proportion to their share of the succession. 
 
 That is the governing principle as to all ordinary obligations 
 which can be thus divided. 
 
 But when the obligation is indivisible this is all different. 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 439 
 
 Each of the debtor's heirs is liable for the whole, subject always 
 to the settlement of claims as among - themselves. 
 
 For we must remember that the articles we are considering 
 treat of the effects of indivisible obligations only as between the 
 creditor and the debtor. As among the debtors themselves, or the 
 creditors themselves, the profit or loss will be divided according- to 
 the relation in which they stand to one another, and it makes no 
 difference from that point of view whether the obligation is 
 divisible or indivisible. 
 
 But although each of the heirs of the creditor may exact in full 
 the execution of an indivisible obligation, because partial pay- 
 ment of it is impossible, the benefit of the payment does not 
 generally belong entirely to the heir who sues. 
 
 It belongs to him and to his co-heirs. And he has no right to 
 prejudice their interests. 
 
 Ho cannot, therefore, release the debt as a whole, nor can he 
 take something instead of the debt. If he does grant such a 
 release, or takes something as an equivalent for payment, this 
 will not prevent another co-heir from suing for the performance 
 of the indivisible obligation. 
 
 But if the other co-heir does so, he must pay the debtor .the 
 value of the share of the co-heir who made the release or received 
 the equivalent. The following is an illustration: — 
 
 John and William owe to Thomas and Edward a debt which 
 is indivisible. 
 
 Thomas releases John from his liability in consideration of 
 receiving L. E. 50. Thomas cannot now sue either John or 
 William. Edward can still sue either John or William for the 
 whole debt as it is indivisible. 
 
 But as Thomas, but for the release, would have been entitled to 
 his share, and Edward cannot keep this, if Edward exacts th'o 
 whole performance from John he must deduct the L. E. 50 or so 
 much of it as would have fallen to Thomas, and if he exacts- 
 performance from William he must deduct L. E. 50 which John 
 has paid or, at any rate, so much of it as belongs to Thomas. 
 (C. C. F. 1224; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1331; Colmet de Santerre, 
 5, n. 159, bis II.) 
 
 When one of the co-heirs is sued for the whole of an indivisible 
 obligation he may demand delay to make the co-heirs parties to 
 the suit, unless the debt is of such a nature that he only can; 
 discharge it. (C. C. F. 1225; C. C. Q. 1130.) 
 
440 THK LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 In the case of the indivisible obligation the defendant's object 
 in demanding that the co-heirs should be mis en cause is that the 
 judgment should find all the co-heirs primarily liable. (Aubry 
 et Ilau, 5th cd. 4, p. 83; Laurent, 17, n. 392; Pand. Franc , 
 Oblig. n. 713.) There are two advantages to be derived from 
 calling in the co-heirs: (1) If the creditor gets a judgment against 
 all the co-heirs, there is a chanoe that he may select another of 
 them for attack, and not the original defendant; and (2) even 
 if the creditor should still attack the original defendant, and he 
 should be condemned in damages for non-performance, this con- 
 demnation in damages is divisible, and, as the co-heirs are all 
 parties, he is liable only for his share, whereas if the others had 
 not been called in he would have been condemned to pay all the 
 damages. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1336; Laurent, 17, n. 392; 
 Pand. Frang. Oblig. n. 714.) It now remains to consider the 
 case stated as an exception in C. C. F. 1225, viz., that the co-heir 
 sued for the whole debt cannot demand delay to make the other 
 co-heirs parties to the suit if the debt is of such a nature that it 
 can be discharged only by himself. Upon this matter Pothier is 
 the safest guide, and he gives as an example the case where the 
 debtor had promised to create a servitude of passage and had died 
 before the servitude was constituted. In the partition the land 
 over which the right of passage was to exist fell to one of the 
 co-heirs. The creditor can sue this co-heir to grant the servitude. 
 The co-heir in this case cannot claim that his co-heirs should be 
 made parties, for a judgment condemning them to execute the 
 obligation would be ineffectual, seeing that he alone can do so. 
 
 But, even here, the defendant can get the co-heirs called in, 
 not, it is true, in order that the judgment shall be against them 
 all, but in order that by the same judgment which finds him finally 
 liable they may be condemned to the extent of their liability in 
 warranty to him. As a general rule, in such a case, there is no 
 recourse, and this dilatory exception is not therefore required, 
 because in the partition the burden of the servitude is taken into 
 account in estimating the shares. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 831; 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1335. The cases to be 
 contrasted with this are: 
 
 (1) When the debt may be discharged indifferently, either by 
 the heir sued or by each of the others, as, for example, if the debtor 
 had contracted to erect a building upon land which belonged to 
 him. Such an obligation would be indivisible, but, so long as 
 the succession is undivided, each of his heirs can equally fulfil it. 
 
DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. 441 
 
 If one of them is sued alone he will be condemned to perform the 
 whole or to pay all the damages, saving- his recourse, unless he 
 avails himself of his right to get the other heirs called in. (C. C. F. 
 1225; C. C. Q. 1130; Pothier, Ohlig. n. 333; Baudry-Lacanl . et 
 Barde, Ohlig. 2, n. 1337.) 
 
 (2) The debt may be one which can only be paid by all the 
 heirs jointly. For example, the debtor has contracted to create 
 a servitude of passage on a route to be afterwards fixed. He dies 
 before the servitude is constituted and his heirs are in indivision. 
 
 It needs the consent of all the co-proprietors to grant the 
 servitude, and if the action is brought against one of thorn he can 
 call the others in. 
 
 But if he does not do this he will be taken as having assumed 
 liability for all the damages, saving his recourse. (Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1337.) 
 
 In this kind of case if one of the heirs pleads that he is willing 
 to perform his share of the obligation, but that another of the 
 co-heirs refuses, ought the heir who is willing to pay to be found 
 liable in damages? This is a controversial question. Pothier 
 answered it in the negative upon the ground that the co-heir who 
 offers to pay his share is not en demeure. (Oblig. n. 334.) And 
 this view is taken by many modern authorities. (Baudry-Lacant. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1337.) 
 
 There are, however, dissentients who argue that the refusal 
 of the co-heir is not either cas fortuit or force majeure, and that 
 nothing else will excuse the performance. 
 
 But they say that if the defendant pays the damages, he is 
 entitled to recover them from the heir by whose fault it is that the 
 obligation was not executed. (Colmet de Santerre, 5, n. 160, bis 
 IV; Pond. Franc,. Oblig. n. 721; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 84, 
 note 20.) Pothier's view seems to be preferable. The heirs are 
 each of them liable for the whole, but this is because the debt is 
 indivisible, and not because they have bound themselves to pay 
 the whole. They are not responsible in any way for each other, 
 and if the obligation fails of fulfilment by the fault of one, there 
 does not seem to be any good ground for making the others 
 responsible for this. 
 
 Indivisibility as applied to obligations with a clause of penalty. 
 
 The French Code states that when an indivisible obligation is 
 accompanied by a penal 'clause, and one of the co-debtors breaks 
 the contract he alone can be sued for the whole penalty; the other 
 
442 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 oo-debtors are liable only for their shares. But when the principal 
 obligation is divisible, the co-debtor who breaks his contract is 
 liable only for his share of the penalty, and there is no actiom 
 against the debtors who have performed their part. (C. C. F. 
 1232, 1233; Aubry et Kau, 5th ed. 4, pp. 85, 93; B.-L. et Barde, 
 2, nos 1374, seq.) The Egyptian law is the same though the 
 code is silent. 
 
 Comparison between indivisibility and joint and 
 several liability. 
 
 There are important differences between these two things, and. 
 the French Code and the Code of Quebec declare: The stipula- 
 tion of joint and several liability does not give to an obligation 
 the character of indivisibility. (C. C. F. 1219; C. C. Q, 1125.) 
 The Code of Quebec adds: — 
 
 Each one of those who have contracted an indivisible obliga- 
 tion is held for the whole, although the obligation have not been 
 contracted jointly and severally. (C. C. Q. 1126.) 
 
 A joint and several obligation is one which is contracted by 
 several debtors together or one which is in favour of several 
 creditors together. 
 
 The joint and several liability is on account of the combination 
 of several debtors. But the indivisible obligation is normally an 
 obligation contracted originally by one debtor, which, contrary 
 to the ordinary rule, is not like his other debts divided among his 
 heirs in proportion to their shares. The debt is indivisible not- 
 withstanding the fact that it is due by several heirs. The chief 
 practical differences between solidarity and indivisibility are: 
 (1) Solidarity does not prevent the division of the debt between 
 the heirs of the debtor or the heirs of the creditor, whereas in- 
 divisibility prevents the division of the debt among the heirs of 
 the debtor or of the creditor. (2) Interruption of prescription in 
 favour of one heir of a joint and several creditor or against one 
 heir of a joint and several debtor does not affect the other heirs, 
 but if the debt were indivisible it would do so in both cases. 
 (3) Solidarity implies the existence of a mandate by which each 
 of the co-de'btors represents the others to the extent above ex- 
 plained, whereas no such reciprocal mandate exists among co- 
 debtors jointly bound to the same indivisible prestation. (C. C. F. 
 2249, 1206; C. C. E. 110/166; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1341; 
 Laurent, 17, n. 404.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 443 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV. 
 
 EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The Egyptian codes enumerate seven modes in which an obliga- 
 tion may become extinct — 
 
 (1) Performance. 
 
 (2) Dissolution, [in the sense of extinction by impossibility of 
 performance, j 
 
 (3) Novation. 
 
 (4) Release. 
 
 (5) Compensation. 
 
 (6) Confusion. 
 
 (7) Prescription. 
 (C. C. E. 158/221.) 
 
 The French Code gives nine modes of extinction of obligation. 
 Seven of them coincide with those of the Egyptian Code, except 
 that the French Code uses the expression " la perte de la chose" 
 instead of the term "dissolution" employed by the Egyptian 
 Code. But this is merely a difference of terminology, because, 
 as will be explained afterwards, the French Code means by " la 
 perte de la chose" the same thing that the Egyptian Code means 
 by "dissolution," namely, that the prestation promised has 
 become physically or legally impossible. Besides these seven 
 modes of extinction, the French Code gives two others, " la nullite 
 ou la rescision," and " Veffet de la condition resolutoire." (C. C. F. 
 1234.) 
 
 The Quebec Code attempts a more complete enumeration. To 
 the nine modes of extinction given in the French Code it adds: 
 (1) the expiration of the time fixed by law or by the parties for 
 the duration of the obligation; (2) the death of the creditor or of 
 the debtor in certain cases; and (3) special causes applicable to 
 particular contracts. (C. C. Q. 1138.) The effect of the resolu- 
 tory condition has been already considered, and the other modes 
 of extinction which are not mentioned in the Egyptian Code in 
 
444 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 this place are not regular and normal modes, but exceptional ways 
 in which certain obligations may be extinguished. (See B.-L. 
 et Barde, 2, n. .1383.) 
 
 The hire of personal services, for example, is dissolved by the 
 death of the person employed. (C. C. E. 411/502.) A life-rent 
 or an alimentary provision comes to an end upon the death of the 
 person entitled to it. Mandate may terminate by the mandator 
 revoking the mandate, or by the mandatary renouncing the man- 
 date, subject in both cases to the rules expressly stated in the 
 law. As M. Hue says, the obligation is in such cases extin- 
 guished by a kind of performance. It comes to an end in one of 
 the ways contemplated by the parties. (Hue, 8, n. 2.) 
 
 There is no need to deal here with these special cases. 
 
 But there is one important general mode of extinction which 
 might have been mentioned in the enumeration, viz., resiliation 
 of the contract by the mutual consent of the parties. This has 
 been referred to earlier. (Supra, p. 5.) 
 
 The seven modes of extinction o-iven in the Egyptian Code 
 will now be explained seriatim: — 
 
 (1) Performance or payment. 
 
 The first mode of extinction of an obligation is its performance. 
 
 The French Code uses the word "payment." Payment as a 
 term of the French law means the fulfilment of the obligation 
 whatever it was. 
 
 It means not only the delivery of a sum of money in satisfaction 
 of an obligation, but the performance of anything to which the 
 parties are respectively obliged. It may, accordingly, consist in 
 giving something or doing something, or in abstaining from doing 
 something. (Aubry et Kau, 5th ed. 4, p. 244; B.-L. et Barde, 
 2, n. 1384.) 
 
 "Payment" in popular language is so much associated with 
 the payment of money that it is not such a good word to describe 
 the performance of the obligation as the word "performance" 
 or the term of the Eoman l&w—solutio — which preserves the figure 
 of the untying of the vinculum juris or lien de droit. (Dig. 50. 
 16. 176.) The Egyptian Code uses "payment" in the narrower 
 sense of payment of money or delivery of fungibles, and employs 
 the term "performance" or, in the French version, V execution, 
 as the general term. (C. C. E. 160/223, 170/233.) 
 
 The term payment in the sense of performance of any obligation 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 445 
 
 is, notwithstanding-, so consecrated by usage that it seems pedantic 
 to avoid it. Every payment presupposes a debt. What has been 
 paid where there is no debt may bo recovered. There can be no 
 recovery of what has been paid in voluntary discharge of a natural 
 obligation. (C. C. F. 1235.) The right to sue for repetition 
 of anything which has been paid without being due has been 
 explained under the head of quasi-contract, and the character of 
 natural obligations has also been explained earlier. 
 
 If a man whose debt has prescribed and who knows that it has 
 prescribed chooses to pay it, he is deemed to have voluntarily 
 paid a natural obligation and, therefore, he cannot recover what 
 has been paid. 
 
 By whom performance may be made. 
 
 " An obligation cannot be performed by any one but the debtor 
 if it results from the nature of that obligation that the creditor 
 has an interest that such should be the case." 
 
 " When performance consists in a payment, it may always be 
 made by a third person, even against the wish of the debtor or 
 the creditor:' (C. C. E. 159, 160/222, 223.) 
 
 It depends on the nature of the obligation and on the intention 
 of the parties whether the performance must be by the debtor 
 himself. In many cases it is obviously to the interest of the 
 creditor that the debtor should perform the obligation in person. 
 If I contract with a celebrated painter to paint my portrait he 
 cannot perform the obligation by getting another to paint the. 
 picture for him. All contracts in which the creditor relies on 
 the personal knowledge or skill of the debtor are of this nature. 
 No contract, then, in which performance by the particular debtor 
 was stipulated for, or is implied, can be performed by another, 
 unless, of course, the creditor consents to let a third party do so. 
 (See supra, p. 227.) But it is quite otherwise when 
 the contract is to pay a, sum of money, or to deliver go 
 much wheat of a certain quality, or to deliver a particular 
 thing. Here the only interest of the creditor is to get 
 his money, his wheat, or the thing for which he has stipulated. 
 It is immaterial to him where it comes from, that is, assuming 
 that the party from whom it comes can validly make the payment. 
 The right of the third party to pay does not depend on his having 
 any interest in the debt, and he may insist on making the payment 
 as-ainst the will of the creditor and without the knowledge of the 
 
446 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 debtor. If the debtor cannot or will not pay his own debt, the 
 least ho can do is to allow his creditor to take payment where he 
 can get it. But what if both the creditor and the debtor are 
 opposed to the third party making- the payment? If they both 
 prefer to leave things as they are, why should a third party bo 
 allowed to interfere? The German Code expressly says that the 
 stranger to the obligation cannot make payment in this case 
 (art. 267, at. 2). This appears to be the French law also, 
 though the code is not explicit on the point. (Colmet de Santerre, 
 5, n. 175, bis X; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 2, n. 1394; Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 245, note 2. See Req. 6 nov. 1907, D. 
 1908. 1. 86.) 
 
 But the Egyptian Code expressly allows it even in this case. 
 The debtor has no interest to object to the payment, because this 
 does not mean that the person who pays the debt which he does' 
 not owe steps into the shoes of the former creditor. The payment 
 extinguished the obligation, and the person paying cannot claim 
 to be subrogated in the rights of the creditor whom he pays except 
 in certain conditions named in the code. (C. C. E. 162/225;, 
 C. C. F. 1236.) He cannot be allowed to make the condition 
 of the debtor worse than it would have been if the debtor had 
 been left to the mercy of the original creditor. If he is not 
 subrogated his claim against the debtor whose debt he has paid 
 will be that of a mandatary if he was authorised to make the 
 payment, and if he had no such authority his action in recoursQ 
 will be, according to circumstances, the action of a negoiiorum 
 gestor or the action de in rem nerso. 
 
 He can recover only to the extent of the benefit which he has 
 conferred. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 2, n. 1399; Laurent, 17, 
 n. 488.) The Egyptian Code is express upon the point: 
 
 Such payment made by a third person gives him a right of 
 recourse against the debtor in respect of the benefit obtained by 
 the latter, up to the ammmt of the sum disbursed. (C. C. E. 
 161/224.) The payer can never make a profit. And the debtor 
 is further protected by C. C. E. 163/226: 
 
 The debtor has the right, when payment has been made against 
 his wish, to decline to recognise in whole or in part any claim 
 against him by the person, who has made a payment on his behalf, 
 if he shows that he had any interest whatever in refusing pay- 
 ment. (See C. A. Alex. 24 dec. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 75.) 
 
 This article does not really add anything, but is intended to 
 make it clearer that the claim is only like that of a negoiiorum. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 417 
 
 gestor. If the debtor, for instance, had the right to plead com- 
 pensation when another paid his debt, he was not benefited by the 
 payment. And, similarly, if the debt was on a contract which 
 was void, or was voidable at his instance. The third party who 
 pays another's debt may do so by compensation when the condi- 
 tions for this are present. (C. A. Alex. 12 mai 1914, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 382.) 
 
 Under the English law the third party who paid the debt, would 
 have no claim at all against the person whose debt he had paid. 
 No man can make himself the creditor of another by paying! 
 that other's debt against his will or without his consent. 
 
 (Per Willes, J., in Johnston v. Royal Mail Steam Packet Co., 
 1867, L. R. 3 C. P. 43, 37 L. J. C. P. p. 48. See Leake on 
 Contracts, 6th ed. p. 44; Anson, Contracts, 14th ed. p. 434. 
 Cf. Hirachand Punamchand v. Temple, 1911, 2 K. B. 330, 80 
 L. J. K. B. 1155; supra, p. 197.) But the French law is 
 different. It may, however, appear that the person who pays the 
 debt of another does so with the intention of making- him a free 
 gift, and not with the view of preserving any right of recourse 
 against him. This is a question of fact, and the presumption is 
 against it, but it maj^, nevertheless, appear from the circumstances 
 that it was so. If the facts indicate that a donation was intended, 
 and it was accepted by the other party, there will be no right of 
 recourse at all. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barcle, Oblig. 2, n. 1399; 
 D. Supp. Oblig. n. 680.) It may also be a question whether if 
 A pays the debt of B he is doing so with his own money., so as 
 to have a recourse against B, or whether he makes the payment 
 with the money of B, the true debtor. According to Larombiere, 
 the presumption is in favour of the second view, but according to 
 Demolombe the presumption is that the person who pays does so 
 with his own money. (Larombiere, on art. 1236, n. 7; Demo- 
 lombe, 2'7, n. 82.) And this is supported by a judgment of the 
 Cow de Cassation. (Cass. 18 fevr. 1901, D. 1901. 1. 303.) 
 
 In any case it is a mere presumption of fact which may be 
 rebutted by other presumptions. 
 
 Obviously, if the person making the payment proposes to sue 
 at once for the full amount this cannot be for the advantage of 
 the debtor. 
 
 He could not have been worse off if he had been left to the 
 original creditor. It is, generally, when the original creditor is 
 threatening to take proceedings, that it may be to his advantage 
 
448 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 for a third party to intervene who is willing to give him time or 
 perhaps to release him. 
 
 Such a third party is not always at hand, but if he does present 
 himself there seems no good reason why the creditor should not 
 be bound to take payment from him, or why the person making 
 tho payment should not have a claim against the debtor, if it is 
 of an equitable kind such as that of a negotiorum gestor. 
 
 Person paying must have capacity. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: For the payment to he valid, the 
 debtor must have capacity to alienate and the creditor capacity 
 to receive. (C. C. E. 165/228.) And this very obvious state- 
 ment is followed by: Nevertheless, the payment of that which 
 is due by a person not having the necessary capacity extinguishes 
 the obligation, provided that he is not prejudiced by such pay- 
 ment. (C. C. E. 166/229.) 
 
 The first of these articles is an improvement on the correspond- 
 ing article of the French Code, which says: — 
 
 Pour payer valablement, il faut etre proprietaire de la chose 
 don-nee en paiement, et capable de Valiener. (C. C. F. 1238.) 
 
 By the old law it was the payment or delivery of the thing 
 which in general passed the property. The payment was an 
 alienation and, therefore, could not be made except by a person 
 capable of alienating. 
 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 496.) But by the modern law a contract 
 for the alienation of a determinate thing makes the purchaser 
 owner before the delivery. (Supra, p. 30.) So that it is clearly 
 incorrect to say that a valid payment must be made by the owner 
 of the thing paid seeing that the seller has, in the ordinary case* 
 ceased to be the owner before that time. Even when the person 
 paying is a minor or other person incapable of alienation, except 
 subject to conditions which have not been fulfilled, the payment 
 extinguishes the obligation, provided the person paying is not 
 prejudiced by the payment. (C. C. E. 166/229.) The incapable 
 who pays a debt clue by him is not prejudiced. And if he pays 
 fungibles to a person to whom they are due, and that person 
 consumes them in good faith, he will not have a revindication. 
 (C. C. F. 1238.) 
 
• EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 449 
 
 To whom payment must be made. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: Performance must be made to the 
 creditor, to his mandatary empowered to this effect, or to the 
 person holding the right to claim execution of the obligation, 
 (C. C. E. 167/230.) 
 
 The French Code has an article: Payment is not valid if 
 made to a creditor who is incapable by law of receiving it, unless 
 the debtor proves that the thing paid has turned to the benefit of 
 such creditor. (C. C. F. 1241.) There is no corresponding 
 article in the Egyptian Code, but there can be no doubt that the 
 law is the' same. These articles may be considered together. In 
 order to take payment the creditor must have the requisite capa- 
 city . So if a man who owes money to a minor, or to an interdicted 
 lunatic, pays the money to his debtor, he may be compelled to pay 
 it over again to the tutor or curator, according to the rule qui paie 
 mal paie deux fois. But he can escape from this necessity if ha 
 can prove that the payment has enured to the benefit of the creditor, 
 as, for instance, if the creditor had bought a house with the money 
 at a fair price. 
 
 And if part of the money has been beneficially applied, the 
 debtor will only need to pay the balance over again. But money 
 spent by the incapable person on luxury— en depenses voluptuaires 
 —has not been beneficially applied. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, 
 n. 1434; Demolombe, 27, n. 197; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 256, note 18.) 
 
 As to payment made to a person having the authority of the 
 creditor, it is to be observed that the authority to take payment 
 may be express or implied. In principle, it is for the deibtor who 
 makes the payment to satisfy himself that the person to whom 
 he pays is authorised to receive the payment. When the contract 
 lays down that payment is to be made to a certain person on 
 behalf of the creditor, but only subject to certain conditions, the 
 debtor must comply strictly with those conditions. (Req. 30, 
 dec. 1912, D. 1915. 1. 53.) A statement in the contract tnat 
 payment is to be made in the office of a certain lawyer or notary 
 does not, in itself, imply that this lawyer or notary has authority 
 to receive payment on behalf of the creditor. (Cass. 19 fevr. 
 1913, D. 1913. 1. 200; Sirey, Table Becennale, 1901—1910, 
 s. v. Paiement, n. 1.) It is in many cases easy to find that such 
 authority was implied from the position of the parties and the 
 practice of business. And it must be remembered that although 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 29 
 
 - 
 
450 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 an incapable person cannot give an agent a better title to take 
 payment than he has himself, yet there is nothing to prevent a 
 person who is himself capable from giving to a minor authority 
 to take a payment for him. (Laurent, 17, n. 522; Dcmolombe, 
 27, n. 136.) Thus a merchant may authorise a clerk who is a 
 minor to receive payment of debts due to the merchant, and such 
 an authority may be express or implied. And it is also a rule of 
 the law of agency that, even though the authority may have been 
 revoked, the payment to the agent is a good payment, if the 
 debtor did not know of the revocation and was in perfect good 
 faith. But he will not be considered to have been in perfect 
 good faith, if it appear that by the exercise of ordinary care he 
 would have discovered that he was paying to a man who had noi 
 longer any right to collect the debt. (Larombiere, on art. 1239, 
 n. 21.) The full discussion of this subject belongs to the law of 
 agency. (See C. C. F. 2005; C. C. E. 530/651; B.-L. et 
 Wahl, Contmts Aleatoires, n. 869; Keq. 21 dec. 1897, D. 98. 
 
 1. 382, note 4. Cf. C. A. Alex. 22 mai 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 
 
 325.) 
 
 » 
 
 Performance made to the person holding the right to claim 
 execution of the obligation. 
 
 This is the phrase used in the Native Code (art. 167). The 
 Mixed Code says: the person possessing the right to the obliga- 
 tion (art. 230). 
 
 What does the code mean by these words? 
 
 Mr. Halton interprets them to mean the assignee of the creditor 
 or the creditors of a creditor who has executed an attachment, — 
 saisie-arret . (1, p. 370.) 
 
 But though payment is valid if made to any one of these, J. 
 think this is not what the aitticle refers to. It is intended to 
 reproduce article 1240 of the French Code: Le paiement fait 
 de bonne foi a celui'qui est en possesion de lacreance, est valable, 
 encore que le possesseur en soit par la suite evince. 
 
 This does not mean the person who happens to be in possession 
 of the document of debt. It means the apparent or ostensible 1 
 creditor, the creancier putatif . Such, for example, is a person 
 who takes a succession as the nearest heir, and is afterwards 
 evicted by a nearer heir who has been discovered later. 
 
 A debtor to the succession who paj r s in good faith to the apparent 
 heir is protected, and his payment extinguishes his debt. (Planiol, 
 
 2, n. 416; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1446; Laurent, 17, n. 545;, 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 451 
 
 Eouen, 28 avril 1874, S. 74. 2. 314; Cass. 10 dec. 1900, S. 1903. 
 1. 33, and note by M. Perron.) The Egyptian Government 
 made a payment to a person who was designed as the curator of 
 its absent creditor by a consular certificate, and was in possession 
 of the grosse of the judgment finding the government liable. 
 It was held that the payment was liberatory. (C. A. Alex. 30 
 nov. 1911, B. L. J. XXIV, 23.) 
 
 Payment cannot prejudice seizures. 
 
 According to the French Code: — 
 
 Payment made by a debtor to his creditor, to the prejudice 
 of a seizure or attachment, is not valid against the seizing or 
 attaching creditors, who may, according to their rights, constrain 
 the debtor to pay a second time, saving in such case only his 
 remedy against the creditor so paid. (C. C. F. 1242.) The 
 effect of seizure by garnishment or attachment is to order the 
 garnishee not to pay the debt to the debtor; it sequestrates the 
 debt in his hands. And the Egyptian law is the same. (See 
 C. Proc. E. 410/471.) Of course, the creditors who challenge 
 the payment on the ground that it was in defiance of their saisies- 
 arrets will not succeed if it is found that they were not really 
 entitled to make the seizures, and, further, they cannot recover 
 more than the loss they have suffered through the action of the 
 creditor. So each of the attaching creditors can recover only the 
 proportion of the debt to which he would have been entitled if the 
 seizure had been respected. 
 
 Performance must be of thing due and cannot be 
 made in part. 
 
 The performance must be that which the parties contemplated, 
 and must be at the time and place stipulated; it cannot be made 
 in part ; subject, however, to the power of the judges, in excep- 
 tional circumstances, to fix a time or times for performance or 
 to grant a moderate extension of time, provided the creditor is 
 not seriously prejudiced thereby. (C. C. E. 168/231.) The 
 French Code says: A creditor cannot be compelled to receive 
 any other thing than the one due to him, although the thing 
 offered be of equal or greater value. (C. C. F. 1243.) People 
 must be held to their bargains. If I buy a horse, the debtor 
 cannot say, " I will not let you have the horse but you can take 
 an elephant which is worth more." (Cass. 6 mars 1876, D. 76. 
 
 29 (2) 
 
 — "T 
 
452 THtf LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 1. 193, dissertation by M. Giboulot; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4 r 
 p. 258; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1459. See supra, p. 362.) But 
 it has been held that when an official copy of a document had been 
 lost, it "was permissible to deliver in its place a second copy seeing- 
 that this was of exactly the same legal effect. (Req. 20 mars 
 1912, D. 1913. 1. 247.) 
 
 Of course, nothing hinders the creditor from consenting to take 
 something different from the thing for which he had at hYst 
 stipulated. If he does so there is said to be not a payment but a 
 "giving in payment" — dation en paiement. (See Cass. 5 fevr. 
 1908, D. 1909. 1. 294.) By the French Code: A debtor cannot 
 compel his creditor to receive payment of his debt in part even if 
 the debt is divisible (art. 1244). Under the French law 
 the court has power to grant the debtor a moderate delay for 
 payment. (C. C. F. 1244.) The Egyptian Code in the article 
 under discussion* gives the same power. (C. C. E. 168/231.) 
 According to the Egyptian jurisprudence, it is only when the debtor 
 is prevented from executing his obligation by some exceptional 
 circumstances, or by an event unforeseen and independent of his 
 will, that the court will grant a deled de grace. (C. A. Alex. 5 
 mars 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 172.) 
 
 The power is to be exercised with great caution as the French 
 article expressly says. (C. A. Alex. 11 mai 1911, B. L. J. 
 XXIII, 315; supra, p. 365.) 
 
 4 
 
 Place of performance. 
 
 The place of performance is, in the absence of agreement to 
 the contrary, the place in which the specific corporeal thing to 
 be delivered is situated. (C. C. E. 169/232.) 
 
 /;,' the case of cadi ami things determined as to kind, payment 
 is presumed to hare been stipulated to be made at the domicile 
 of tli" debtor. (C. C. E. 170.) These articles are similar to 
 the article of the French Code though with slight differences. 
 The French article is: — 
 
 Le payement doit etre execute dans le lieu designe par la con- 
 vention. Si 1c lien ii'i/ est pax designe, Je pagrmcuf, lorsqu'U 
 s'agit d'un corps certain et del ermine, doit etre fait dans h lieu 
 ou etait. uu temps de V obligation, la chose qui en fait Vobfpt. 
 Hors ces deux cas, le payement doit etre fait au domicile du 
 debiteur. (C. C. F. 1247. 
 
 The place of payment depends on the intention of the parties, 
 but this intention may he implied as well as expressed. In the 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 453 
 
 case of a certain specific thing the law impii is thai il is to be paid 
 at the place where it was when the contract was mad", unless 
 there is a stipulation to the contrary. So it has b son held as to a 
 loan of specific things, la rent Hut ion d'objeU en nature qui ont 
 etc pretes doit, en Vabsence de convention contraire, s'operer au 
 lieu oil Vemprunt a ete realise. (Bordeaux, 29 avr. 1898. I). 98. 
 2. 228.) And likewise when fungibles had been .sold by a vente 
 a terme it was held the payment was to be at the domicile of the 
 debtor. (Bcsancon, 21 fevr. 1890, D. 91. 2. 140. ) And in an 
 Egyptian case where a contract of life-insurance had been made 
 with an English company through an agent in Egypt it was held 
 that the payment was due in London. (C. A. Alex. 2 dec. 1915, 
 B. L. J. XXVIII, 43.^ There are one or two cases as to which 
 there are special provisions. The rule is that, apart from- stipu- 
 lation, the creditor must seek out the debtor and demand payment 
 at his domicile. (Demolombe, 27. n. 266: Aubry et Ram 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 267; D. N. C. C. art. 1247, n. 31.) 
 
 A money debt is presumably querable and not portable. So 
 in the case of the lease of a house the landlord must send for his 
 rent. And the fact that the lessee has at the request of the lessor, 
 on several occasions, sent the rent to the lessor's domicile, docs not 
 amount to a renunciation for the future by the lessee of his right 
 to delay payment till it is demanded at his domicile. ;C. A. 
 Alex. 5 janv. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 60.) 
 
 The fact that the previous instalments of a debt have been 
 taken by the debtor to the creditor, or paid at a place other than 
 the debtor's domicile, does not amount to a renunciation on his 
 part of his right to have the demand for payment made at his 
 domicile for the future. The renunciation of a right is not pre- 
 sumed. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblicj. 2, n. 1510; Demo- 
 lombe, 27, n. 271; Laurent, 17, n. 593.) 
 
 If the debtor has changed his domicile between the date of the 
 contract and the time of payment it will be at his new domicile 
 that the demand must be made. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 549.) And, 
 even if the change of domicile involves some expense to the 
 creditor in following him to his new address, the better opinion 
 appears to be that he cannot claim this expense from the debtor. 
 The law creates the presumption that payment is to be at the 
 debtor's domicile, and it does not make any reservation of this 
 kind. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1508; Laurent, 17, n. 592.) Some 
 authorities, however, are of a different opinion as to the right to 
 recover such expenses. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 267, note 15.) 
 
 But if the agreement is that payment is to be made at the 
 
454 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 domicile of the creditor, and the creditor changes his domicile* 
 the debtor is not obliged to follow the creditor to his new domicile 
 unless the agreement so declares. The presumption is that the 
 parties meant the creditor's domicile at the date of the contract. 
 The debtor may demand that the creditor should elect a domicile, 
 in this place to receive the payment. In questions of doubt the 
 law is in favour of the debtor. (Pothier, Ohlig. n. 549; Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1505; Demolombe, 27, n. 273.) 
 Even when the agreement says that the debt shall be portable, 
 as, for example, when a policy of fire-insurance provides that the 
 premiums shall be paid at the office of the company's agent, it 
 may, nevertheless, be found that this right has been waived by 
 the practice of collecting the premiums as they fell due. (Cass, 
 4 nov.-1891, D. 92. 1. 313; Paris, 2 mars 1893, D. 93. 2. 256; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1511.) 
 
 Expenses of payment. 
 
 The expenses of performance must be borne by the debtor. 
 (C. C. E. 171/234.) It is the debtor's business to discharge 
 his debts, and, therefore, it is natural that the cost of doing so 
 should fall on him . The " expenses of payment " include accessory 
 expenses which the payment may entail, such as those of the 
 cancellation of a hypothec which secures the debt. (C. A. Alex. 
 30 dec. 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 85.) In regard to the payment 
 which consists in the delivery of merchandise, it is his business to 
 have it weighed, measured, and packed or prepared in such a 
 manner as to be ready for delivery. Unless it is otherwise stipu- 
 lated, or unless there is a usage to the contrary, the cost of con- 
 veying the thing from the seller to the buyer falls upon the 
 latter. (C. C. E. 283, 284/355, 356; C. C. F. 1608; C. C. Q. 
 1495. See D. Rep. Vente, n. 273; Cass. 3 juill. 1913, D. 1915. 
 1. 65.) 
 
 Proof of payment. 
 
 The proof of payment is subject to the ordinary rules, and if 
 the debt was a civil and not a commercial debt, and it exceeds 
 P. T. 1,000, its extinction by payment cannot be proved by parole.. 
 (Laurent, 49, n. 457; D. N."'C. €. art. 1341, nos. 97 seq.; Eeq. 31 
 mars 1874, D. 75. 1. 229; D. N. C. C. art. 1247, n. 47.) But 
 payment of a commercial debt may be proved by parole. (Lyon- 
 Caen et Benault, Traite de Droit Commercial, 3, n. 47; D. Rep. 
 Oblig. n. 4963.) Whether when the debt exceeds P. T. 1,000, 
 a payment on account consisting of a sum less than P. T. 1,000 
 can be proved by parole has been disputed. Panel. Franc. Oblig. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 455 
 
 n. 3644; D. N. C. Cart. 1341, n. 110.) When the object of such, 
 evidence is to interrupt prescription of a debt over P. T. 1,000, 
 proof by witnesses is inadmissible. The article in the Egyptian 
 Code must be interpreted in the -light of the French law. (C. C. E. 
 215/280; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 306, n. 20. See C. A. 
 Alex. 9 janv. 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 86.) The delivery of the 
 title of the debt to the debtor affords a strong presumption of pay- 
 ment, but the creditor may still prove that the title was given to 
 the debtor for some other purpose; or that he got possession of it by 
 fraud, etc. (C. C. E. 219, 220/284, 285; C. C. F. 1282, 1283; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 341. See Cass. 26 fevr. 1901, S. 
 1901. 1. 493; D. Rep. Oblig. n. 2569; C. A. Alex. 13 fevr. 
 1896, B.L.J. VIII, 117.) 
 
 The delivery of a receipt for a later instalment of a debt raises 
 a presumption that earlier instalments have been paid. (D. Rep. 
 Oblig. n. 2592; C. A. Alex. 28 mai 1891, B. L. J. Ill, 360.) 
 The French jurisprudence is very strict in its requirement of 
 proof of payment. Proof that the creditor sent a post-office order 
 for the sum due is not sufficient; nor even proof that the order 
 was cashed in the regular way. 
 
 Le debiteur ne pent etre libere dans ce cas que par la produc- 
 tion d'un acquit emunant sans contestation possible de son crean- 
 cier. (Trib. Com.de la Seine, 9 fevr. 1912, D. 1914.5.2.) The 
 production by a bank of a cheque drawn upon the bank and 
 payable to bearer is proof that the bank has paid the sum. The 
 indorsement of the person who receives the money is not necessary 
 to prove payment. (C. A. Alex. 15 juin 1916, B.L.J. XXVIII, 
 431.) 
 
 Payment with subrogation. 
 
 When payment is made by the debtor the debt is extinguished, 
 and any accessory obligation which may exist, such as the obliga- 
 tions of sureties, and any real securities, such as hypothecs, fall 
 to the ground at the same time. The extinction of , the principal, 
 debt necessarily involves the extinction of all the accessory debts. 
 And this is the case, also, when the payment of the debt is made 
 not by the debtor, but by a third party, unless the extinction of 
 the accessories is prevented by what is called subrogation. Subro- 
 gation is specially dealt with in the Egyptian Code in two articles. 
 (C. C. E. 162, 164/225, 227.) The former of these articles in 
 speaking of the case of payment of a debt made by a third person 
 says: To such third persons pass, by way of security for the 
 
456 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 new debt so created, the securities which attached to the discharged 
 obligation, but only in the following cases : — 
 
 (1) When the creditor has agreed, at the time of payment, to 
 transfer such securities to him; 
 
 (2) When such third person was liable for the debt with or 
 for the debtor ; 
 
 (3) When such third person has paid a creditor having a privi- 
 lege or hypothec ranking before him, or when, being the pur- 
 chaser of an immoveable, he devotes the price to paging creditors 
 having hypothecs over such immoveable; 
 
 (4) When the law expressly grants subrogation. 
 
 The second article deals with the peculiar case of subrogation 
 by the. debtor. It runs: The debtor may also, without the co- 
 operation of the creditor, transfer the securities attaching to the 
 original debt for the benefit of any one who supplies him with 
 that with which payment is intended to be made. The corre- 
 sponding article of the Mixed Code adds, as a restriction, pro- 
 vided the loan and its employment are verified by a legalised 
 document. (C. C. M. 227.) 
 
 These articles are based upon three articles of the French Code, 
 but differ from them in several points. It will be well to give the 
 French articles in full: 
 
 La subrogation dans les droits du creancier au profit cVune HerCe 
 personne qui le paie, est ou conventionnelle ou legale. 
 
 Cette subrogation est conventionnelle : 
 
 1°. Lorsque le creancier recevant son payement d'une tierce 
 personne la subroge dans ses droits, actions, privileges ou hypo- 
 theques contre le debiteur : cette subrogation doit etre expresse 
 et faite en meme temps que le payement ; 
 
 2°. Lorsque le debiteur emprunte une somme a Veffet de payer 
 sa dette, et de subroger le preteur dans les droits du creancier. II 
 faut, pour que cette subrogation soit valable, que Vacte d'emprunt 
 et la quittance soient passes devant notaires; que dans Vacte 
 d'emprunt il soit declare que la somme a ete empruntee pour faire 
 le payement, et que dans la quittance il soit declare que la paye- 
 ment a ete fait des deniers fournis a cet effet par le nouwau 
 creancier. Cette subrogation sopere sans le concours de la volonte 
 du creancier. 
 
 La subrogation a lieu de plein droit : 
 
 1°. Au profit de celui qui, cfant hd-meme creancier, paie un 
 autre creancier qui lui est preferable a reason de ses privileges ou 
 hypotheques ; 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 457 
 
 2°. Au profit de Vacquereur d'un immeuble, qui emploie le 
 prix de son acquisition au payement des creanciers anxquels cet 
 heritage etait hypotheque ; 
 
 3°. Au profit de celui qui, etant tenu avec aVautres ou pour 
 d'autres au payement de la dette, avait interet de I'acquitter ; 
 
 4°. An profit de Vheritier beneficiaire qui a paye de ses deniers 
 les dettes de la succession. (C. C. F. arts. 1249, 1250, 1251.) 
 
 Special points of difference between French and 
 Egyptian laws. 
 
 (1) The Egyptian Code speaks of a new debt being created, 
 whereas the French Code implies that the old debt is kept alive. 
 
 (2) Ths French Code requires an acte authentique when a 
 debtor subrogates a new creditor in room of the old creditor. 
 
 The Egyptian Native Code does not make this requirement 
 though the Mixed Code does. These jooints will be referred to 
 later. 
 
 Subrogation, according to the French law, is a fiction in virtue 
 of which a debt which is paid, and, therefore, extinguished quoad 
 the creditor, is nevertheless kept alive against the debtor. 
 
 It is a means by which a person who pays the debt of another 
 may obtain some security for its repayment to him. We have 
 already seen that even a stranger to a debt who pays it will have 
 a claim against the debtor according to the principles of 
 negotiorum gestio to the extent to which the debtor benefited by 
 the intervention. But in this case all that he has is a personal 
 claim against the debtor whose debt he has discharged. It may 
 be, however, that the creditor holds securities for the payment of 
 the debt, such as hypothecs, or pledges, or bonds of suretyship. 
 In such a case, if the person who pays the debt obtains from the 
 ereditor a transfer of these securities he will be in a much stronger 
 position. In the case of an unsecured debt, the person who pays 
 can have no more than an action against the debtor and subroga- 
 tion will be of no advantage. But where the debt is secured, it is 
 obviously an advantage to the person who pays the debt to get 
 the securities transferred to him. The creditor who gets his money 
 has no further need for the securities, and the sureties who were 
 liable to the original creditor are no worse off than they were 
 before by now becoming liable to the new creditor. Subrogation 
 is, therefore, an advantage all round. Take, for example, such 
 a common case as this. A debt is secured by a hypothec, and 
 being due and unpaid, the hypothecary creditor is threatening to 
 
 
458 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 seize and sell the debtor's property. A friend of the debtor as 
 willing to advance him the money to pay off the hypothec, but 
 does not wish to lend the money on the personal security of the 
 debtor. If, when he pays the money, the creditor subrogates 
 him in his place in the hypothec, the lender gets the security which 
 he desires, and the debtor is relieved from the necessity of seeing 
 his property sold at what may be an unfavourable moment for 
 him. Subrogation bears some resemblance to the sale of debts 
 and rights of action— transport des creances or cession des creances. 
 (C. C. E. 349/435; C. C, F. 1689; C. C. Q. 1570.) 
 
 But there are, in fact, essential differences between the two 
 things; the object of subrogation is to come to the aid of the 
 debtor, whereas the object of a person who buys a debt is to make 
 a speculation. It follows from this difference that if the pea-son 
 subrogated got the debt discharged by paying less than the full 
 amount due, his claim against the sureties, etc., will be limited' 
 to what he has actually paid, whereas the person who buys a debt 
 of L. E. 1,000 for L. E. 500 can still sue the debtor for L. E. 
 1,000. And there are other differences which need not here be 
 explained. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1521; Aubry 
 et Eau, 5th ed. 4, p. 283; C. A. Alex. 28 nov. 1901, B. L. J. 
 XIV, 28.) 
 
 Sometimes it may be a question whether an agreement was of 
 the nature of subrogation or was' intended to be a sale of the debt. 
 
 If it appears that the payment was made when the debt was 
 not due, the presumption would seem to be that it was a sale of 
 the debt, but if the debt was due, and, especially, if legal pro- 
 ceedings had been threatened or taken, the presumption Avould 
 be that the person who made the payment did so to relieve the 
 debtor and with a view to subrogation. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 286; Dijon, 18 juill. 1893, D. 94. 2. 405.) 
 
 Subrogation is commonly spoken of as being either (1) con- 
 ventional or (2) legal. (C. C. F. 1250, 1251.) But if we use 
 the term " conventional " in this connection, we must remember 
 that it does not imply the consent of both the debtor and the 
 creditor. Conventional subrogation may take place in consequence 
 of an agreement made with a third party either by the creditor or 
 by the debtor. 
 
 Conventional subrogation. 
 
 (1) Conventional subrogation occurs by the consent of the 
 creditor, when the creditor on receiving payment from a third 
 person subrogates him in all his rights against the debtor. This 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 459' 
 
 subrogation must be express and made at the same time as .the 
 payment. 
 
 (2) It takes place by the consent of the debtor when the debtor 
 borrows a sum for the purpose of paying his debt, and of subro- 
 gating the lender in the rights of the creditor. Under the Mixed 
 Code, it is necessary 'to the validity of the subrogation in this case 
 that the act of loan and the employment be verified by a legalised 
 document. (C. C. M. 227.) The Mixed Code probably intends 
 to retain the requirements laid down in the French Code, ;viz., 
 that in the act of loan it be declared that the sum has been bor- 
 rowed for the purpose of paying the debt. The French Code 
 requires also that in the acquittance it be declared that the pay- 
 ment has been made with the moneys furnished by the new creditor 
 for that purpose. 
 
 The Egyptian Mixed Code does not make this requirement, 
 and we cannot consider it to be implied. (De Hults, Rep. vo. 
 Execution-pay ement, n. 102.) 
 
 This subrogation takes effect without the consent of the creditor. 
 There is, of course, nothing to prevent the two declarations being 
 made in one and the same deed. 
 
 The object of requiring a legalised document is to prevent 
 fraud of the following kind: a debtor whose immoveables are 
 charged with several hypothecs, amounting in the whole to more 
 than .their value, pays off the first hypothec. This greatly im- 
 proves the position of the hypothecary creditors who remain. But 
 if, subsequently, the debtor wants to borrow more money, and 
 cannot do so without giving security, he might antedate the deed 
 of loan, and declare in it that the lender had advanced the money 
 to pay off the hypothec already discharged. In this way he would 
 revive the old extinguished hypothec which would again take pre- 
 cedence of the later securities. (Planiol, 2, n. 487.) The Native 
 Code does not require a legalised document and under it the risk 
 of this fraud still occurs. 
 
 We see that there are two varieties of conventional subrogation: 
 
 (1) The subrogation which occurs when the creditor consents 
 to subrogate the person who pays him, and 
 
 (2) That which occurs without the consent of the creditor when 
 the debtor borrows money to pay his debts, and subrogates the 
 new lender in the creditor's rights. In the first case it is for the. 
 creditor to decide whether he will take the payment and subrogate 
 the person paid. He is bound to take payment from a third 
 person, but he is not bound to subrogate him. If he chooses to 
 
460 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 do so, ho must expressly say so, though, as the law does not insisit 
 upon sacramental words, it is not necessary to use the word " sub- 
 rogation." Further, the subrogation must be made at the same 
 time as the payment, for, otherwise, the discharge of the debt 
 by a pure and simple payment would extinguish the debt with 
 all its accessories, and these could not be revived afterwards. The 
 subrogation generally is in all the rights, but this is not essential. 
 The creditor may subrogate the person who pays in some of his 
 rights, but not in all; for example, in a hypothec, but not in a 
 claim against a surety. (See Req. 30 dec. 1903, D. 1904. 1. 
 127.) Subrogation can in no case give the person subrogated 
 any greater rights than the former creditor had. (Liege, 3 mars 
 1886, D. 88. 2. 70.) 
 
 The French law makes no other requirements in this case; the 
 subrogation docs not need to be made by a legalised document; 
 it ma}- be made by private writing or even by a verbal declaration, 
 subject to the difficulties of proof. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 2, n. 1525, 1; Demolombe, 27. n. 377.) And the Egyptian 
 Native Code is to the same effect. In practice, however, it is 
 almost always made by a legalised document, and this is much 
 safer because the subrogation contained in a private writing in a 
 question with third parties would have no certain date. The 
 Egyptian Mixed Code requires a legalised document in this case 
 also. (C. C. M. 225.) 
 
 Legal subrogation. 
 
 Subrogation takes place by the sole operation of law and without 
 demand: — 
 
 (1) In favour of a creditor who pays another creditor whose 
 claim is preferable to his by reason of privilege or hypothec; 
 
 (2) In favour of the purchaser of an immoveable property who 
 pays the price to a creditor to whom the property is hypothecated; 
 
 (3) In favour of a party who pays a debt for which he is liable 
 with others or for others, when he has an interest in paying it. 
 
 There are here three cases stated of legal subrogation, and they 
 are the only ones which the code recognises. (As to subrogation 
 in cases of insurance, see Planiol, 2, n. 2164, and n. 2174. note 3; 
 D. N. C. C. IV, p. 893, n. 1711.) The subrogation takes place 
 de piein droit, and the person who pays cannot demand from the 
 creditor any deed declaring him to be subrogated. (C. A. Alex. 
 14 fevr. 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 138. See C. A. Alex. 17 avril 
 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 286.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 461 
 
 (1) This is what the Roman law calls the jus offerendi. 
 (Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. 785.) The postponed creditor can 
 always pay off the creditor whose claim is prior to his own on 
 account of a privilege or a hypothec. So a creditor who has a 
 hypothec can pay off a creditor who has a privilege, because 
 privileges come before hypothecs. And the holder of a second 
 hypothec can pay off the holder of the first. The advantage of 
 this is that the prior creditor might be going to sell at a time 
 unfavourable for the postponed creditor. The only interest of 
 the prior creditor is to realise enough to pay himself. But the 
 postponed creditor may think that the property may rise in value,, 
 and that, if the sale is delayed, there will be enough to pay both 
 the creditors. The right to legal subrogation exists only when 
 the claim of the prior creditor is preferable by his " having a 
 privilege or hypothec ranking before him." These words are 
 strictly interpreted. A creditor who has a pledge enjoys a pri- 
 vilege. But a creditor who has merely the right of antichresis, 
 that is to say, the right to retain possession of an immoveable, 
 and to take the fruits in lieu of interest, has no privilege in the 
 sense of this article. He has the right to the property of the 
 fruits, but he has no privilege over the immoveable itself. 
 (Larombiere, on art. 1251, n. 9; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Ohlig. 
 2, n. 1546; Couture v. Gregoire, 1912, R. J. Q. 21 K. B. 488.) 
 
 But it is not necessary that the creditor who pays should have 
 either a privilege or a hypothec. The code makes no distinction, 
 and therefore a chirographic creditor who pays the debt of a 
 privileged or a hypothecary creditor is entitled to subrogation. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1542, 1; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 294; 
 Caen, 26 nov. 1870, D. 73. 2. 181.) Upon this point, the Roman 
 law and the old French law were different from the modern law. 
 (Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. 785; Demolombe, 27, n. 458.) 
 
 Purchaser of immoveable who pays price to 
 hypothecary creditors. 
 
 (2) This is the following case: John lends L. E. 1,000 to 
 William, who gives him a hypothec over his house, and also finds 
 a security. William sells the house to Thomas. Thomas, wishing 
 to get rid of the hypothec in favour of John, pays him the L. E. 
 1,000. He will be subrogated in all John's rights, and will , 
 consequently, have a right to sue the surety. 
 
 Or, again, suppose there are several creditors holding hypothecs 
 
462 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 ■ of different; ranks. The purchaser if he pays the price to the 
 vendor will be liable to be sued by these creditors if the vendor, 
 has not paid them. If the price is enough to pay them all the 
 purchaser instead of paying- the vendor can pay the creditors 
 
 ■ directly and thus avoid this risk. 
 
 But if the price is not enough to do this, he can pay off the 
 hypothecs in order of rank so far as the money will go. Suppose 
 die pays off a first and a second hypothec. A third hypothec still 
 remains. The creditor who holds it has the right to seize and sell 
 the immoveable. But, seeing- that, the purchaser is subrogated 
 in the place of the creditors paid off, there will be no advantage 
 to the third creditor in having the immoveable seized and sold, 
 unless it can be sold for a price more than sufficient to pay them. 
 The purchaser can always recover the price. This will generally 
 prevent the creditor from taking action. 
 
 Subrogation is useful to the purchaser in this way, but he 
 may prefer to adopt a still better method, viz., that of purge, 
 though this is not so common in Egypt as one would expeat.. 
 (C. C. E. 075/698; C. C. Pro. M. 675; Grandmoulin, Suretes,, 
 n. 526; Planiol, 2, n. 498.) 
 
 "Purchaser" in C. C. E. 162/225, in the French version, 
 acquereur, is not limited to an onerous purchaser . A donee who 
 has paid out of his own pocket the hypothecary creditor, enjoys 
 the benefit of subrogation no less than an onerous purchaser. If 
 there were any doubt about this, it would be removed by the fact 
 that the donee obtains legal subrogation under the next head, 
 seeing that he is bound with others for the debt. (Baudry-Lacant.i 
 et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1555; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 299.) 
 
 Persons liable with or for the debtor. 
 
 (3) John lends L. E. 1,000 to William and' Thomas, who 
 bind themselves jointly and severally to repay it. William pays 
 the whole debt. *He is subrogated in all John's rights against 
 Thomas. But there is no legal subrogation unless the party 
 paying was himself bound to pay the debt. It is not enough 
 that he has an interest to pay it. He must be liable with others 
 or for others. (Cass. 5 juin 1896, D. 96. 1. 468.) And there 
 can be no question of subrogation when the debt was not paid by 
 the person who claims to be subrogated. (C. A. Alex. 14 juin 
 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 362; C. A. Alex. 8 mars 1917, B. L. J. 
 XXIX, 282.) It is not, however, necessary that the two debtors 
 should be bound in the same way to entitle the one of them who 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 463 
 
 pays to bo subrogated in the creditor's right against the other. 
 (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1557; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 300.) 
 A surety who is bound jointly and severally with the debtor and 
 pays the debt enjoys the benefit of subrogation. (Toulouse, 27 
 dec. 1911, D. 1913. 2. 65, and note by M. Donnedieu de Vabres; 
 C. A. Alex. 8 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 134.) 
 
 Effects of subrogation. 
 
 Bv C. C. F. 1252; C. C. Q. 1157:' The subrogation declared 
 in the preceding articles takes effect as well against sureties as 
 against principal debtors. It cannot prejudice the rights of the 
 creditor when he has been paid in part only. In such case, he 
 mag enforce his rights for whatever remains due, in preference 
 to him from whom' he has received payment in part. (See Req. 
 8 dec. 1903, D. 1904. 1. 193.) The Egyptian Code has no 
 similar article, but, no doubt, it intends to preserve the same rule. 
 The principle is laid down in the case of suretyship, and it would 
 seem that it is a general rule. (C.,C. E. '505/617. See C. A. 
 Alex. 25 fevr. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 110; C. A. Alex. 25 juin 
 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 468; C. A. Alex. 20 fevr. 1917, B. L. J. 
 XXIX, 235.) 
 
 The effects of subrogation are the same whether the subroga- 
 tion is conventional or legal. The person subrogated has all the 
 rights and the actions which the creditor had against sureties and 
 others, as well as against the principal debtor. If the creditor 
 had the right to the vendor's action of dissolution of sale for th,e 
 non-payment of the price the subrogate will have the right also, 
 (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1567; Aubry et Rau, 5th eel. 4, 
 p. 306; Orleans, 6 nov. 1891, D. 93. 2. 33.) If the tiers- 
 detenteur pays the hypothecary creditor he is subrogated in the 
 hypothec which may cover other immoveables as well as that of 
 which he is the holder. (C. A. Alex. 11 juin 1913, B. L. J). 
 XXV, 440.) But the sureties or other guarantors are securities 
 for the payment of the whole debt, and, therefore, if the third 
 person has paid only a part of the debt, the creditor is still entitled 
 to enforce his rights against the sureties, etc., for the part which 
 remains unpaid in preference to the subrogate. (C. A. Alex. 
 25 juin 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 468; C. A. Alex. 20 fevr. 1917, 
 B. L. J. XXIX, 235.) If the debt was an unsecured debt, and 
 the third person pays a part of it, the creditor will not enjoy any, 
 preference, because the person who has paid the part of the debt 
 
464 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 will have a claim for reimbursement of it against the debtor, and 
 this is a simple chirographic debt as much as the claim of the 
 creditor. He and the creditor will rank equally if the debtor was 
 insolvent. Neither of them will have any preference, because 
 the person who has paid the part of the debt does not need to claim 
 in his character of subrogate, but simply as a negotiorum gestor. 
 (B.-L. et Barcle, 2, n. 1571; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 313, 
 note 91.) 
 
 It is clear that subrogation cannot give to the person subrogated 
 any rights which did not belong to the person to whom he is 
 subrogated. (C. A. Alex. 30 mai 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 375; 
 C. A. Alex. 10 dec. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 85.) And in one 
 case his right is more restricted. The joint and several surety who 
 pays the debt due to a creditor-pledgee cannot sue his fellow- 
 surety for the whole amount though the creditor could have done 
 so. (C. A. Alex. 8 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 134.) 
 
 Various theories of subrogation. 
 
 It has already been mentioned that the Egyptian Code in 
 speaking of subrogation uses language which is consistent with 
 the French theory on that subject, and this point was reserved 
 for further consideration. The theory which is now almost uni- 
 versally accepted in France is that subrogation, whether legal or 
 conventional, is a legal fiction, according to which the obligation 
 which is extinguished as to the old creditor by the payment made 
 to him by the third party, is, nevertheless, kept alive as regards 
 the person making the payment. The person making the payment 
 is considered, as it were, to be one and the same person with the 
 old creditor. There is a transmission of the debt to him, though 
 it is extinguished as regards the relations between the debtor and 
 the former creditor. There is no new debt but an old debt which 
 is kept alive in spite of the change of creditor. This was the 
 theory of Pothier. (Oblig. n. 559.) And it is clear from the 
 Travaux preparatoires that the French codifiers intended to pre- 
 serve it. The French Code speaks in various places of subroga- 
 tion causing the new creditor to be substituted " in the rights " 
 of the former creditor, and this language can only mean that he 
 succeeds to him in the creance. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 277, 
 and note 2; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1518; Demolombe, ,27, 
 n. 320; D. N. C. C. art. 1249, n. 5; Cass. 22 nov. 1893, D. 
 94. 1. 153; C. Cass, de Belgique, 19 janv. 1905, D. 1906. 2. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 465 
 
 412.) But, although this theory now holds the field in France, 
 there is another system which is supported by a few writers. 
 They argue that the law calls the operation " payment with sub- 
 rogation." This language implies that there is a genuine pay- 
 ment. Now, if there is a payment the debt must be extinguished, 
 and it can only be the accessories of the debt, — the securities 
 which attached to it — -which pass to the person making the pay- 
 ment. The nature of the operation is the extinction d'une creance 
 avec transport de ses garanties sur la creance nouvelle qui vient 
 la remplacer. (Marcade, sur l'art. 1236, 4, n. 672; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1249,n. 3.) 
 
 Another way of treating the matter is to say simply that we 
 must apply the language of the code. Subrogation according to 
 the code is a hybrid operation and we must accept it as such. 
 There is no gain in resorting to legal fictions in order to make the 
 operation more intelligible. (Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 91.) 
 
 The obvious criticism of the theory of Marcade is that if the 
 debt is paid and extinguished the securities must fall to the 
 ground. As the Mixed Court of Appeal expresses it: cm ne 
 concevrait pas que I'accessoire subsist at apres V extinction du 
 principal. (C. A. Alex. 8 mars 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 187.) 
 Notwithstanding the fact that this theory has little in its favour, 
 it has been supposed that it is the theory which is accepted by the 
 Egyptian Code. That code speaks of the "new debt," and says 
 that the securities which attach to the " discharged obligation " 
 pass to the new debt. It is difficult to reconcile this language 
 with the prevailing theory of the French law, viz., that there is no 
 new debt at all. (C. C. E. 162/225; De Hults, Rep. vo. Execu- 
 tion-pay ement, n. 123.) 
 
 Practical consequences of the difference of theory. 
 
 If the debt itself is not transferred by the subrogation, the 
 third party who is subrogated cannot make use of an executory 
 title which the former creditor possessed. If he desires to pro- 
 ceed to execution on the property of the debtor he must get 
 judgment. Nor, in strict logic, ought the subrogate to have the 
 benefit of a privilege which attaches to the debt, for a creditor 
 is privileged by reason of the nature of his claim, and this privi- 
 leged character cannot be transferred to another claim. If the 
 claim itself is not transferred to the person subrogated it is 
 difficult to see why he should enjoy the privilege. (B.-L. et 
 
 w. — VOL. II. 30 
 
466 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1519.) But there is an Egyptian decision 
 in the contrary sense, and this is in accordance with the intention 
 of the legislator. When the code speaks of paying a creditor 
 " having a privilege or hypothec ranking before him," it means 
 that the subrogate succeeds to this privilege or hypothec. (C. A. 
 Alex. 18 janv. 1894, B. L. J. VI, 194.) But upon the theory 
 of Marcade and others, the subrogate would not succeed to the 
 right of an action to resiliate the contract, for example, the right 
 to demand the dissolution of a sale for non-payment of the price. 
 For this is not a "security attached to the obligation." (De 
 Hults, Rep. vo. Execution, n. 126.) This theory makes sub- 
 rogation very similar to novation by change of the creditor, and 
 yet there are different rules laid down as to the transmission of 
 securities in that case. (C. C. E. 188/252; De Hults, Rep. vo. 
 Execution-pay ement, n. 121.) 
 
 Has Egyptian Code adopted new theory? 
 
 M. de Hults maintains that the Egyptian legislator has aban- 
 doned the traditional theory of the legal fiction, and has adopted 
 the theory of Marcade and others that there is a new debt. He 
 says that the Egyptian law considere la creance payee commie 
 definitiv ement eteinte, a Vegard de tout le monde {op. cit. n. 
 126). But, in spite of the use of the expression "new debt" in 
 the Egyptian codes, the Mixed Court of Appeal holds that the 
 Egyptian law is in accordance with the traditional view: En par- 
 lant de V obligation eteinte le legislateur a voulu dire qu'elle etait 
 eteinte a Vegard du creancier originairepnais il a entendu, evidem- 
 ment, que la dette continue a subsister avec les guaranties consenties 
 par le debiteur au profit de son obligation. (C. A. Alex. 8 mars 
 1916, E. L J. XXVIII, 187.) 
 
 Imputation of payments. 
 
 A debtor who owes several debts to the same creditor can, when 
 he makes a payment, declare to which of the debts the payment 
 is to be imputed. By the Egyptian Code: Payments are im- 
 puted to the debt indicated by the debtor, or, in the absence of 
 indication, to that which' he has the most interest in discharging. 
 (C. C. E. 172/235; C. A. Alex. 27 mai 1908, B. L. J. XX, 
 258; C. A. Alex. 5 juin 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 382.) The 
 Egyptian Code is very meagre and, apparently, it intends to state 
 the French law in an abridged form. If this is so, we may apply 
 the French rules, and, according to the French Code, if the debtor 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 467 
 
 does not make such an imputation it may be made by the creditor, 
 and if neither the debtor nor the creditor makes it, the imputai iop 
 is made by the law. The rules of the French law on the subject 
 are based on the Roman law. (Dig. 46. 3. 1; Girard, Manuel, 
 5th cd. 690.) 
 
 As regards several debts equally due, the debtor has a choice 
 which of them he will pay. The creditor cannot without the 
 debtor's consent impute the payment to the earlier of the two 
 debts. And if a debtor has instructed an agent to make a pay- 
 ment for him imputing the payment to a certain debt, the agent 
 cannot alter the imputation. In making the imputation the debtor 
 will naturally want to pay first the debt which is the more onerous. 
 If one of the debts is unsecured, and for the other he is bound 
 together with a surety, it is quite open to him, if he choose, to 
 direct the creditor to impute the payment to the unsecured debt. 
 
 But the doctrine of imputation of payments implies always 
 that the debtor owes to the same creditor several debts of money 
 or of fungibles of the same kind. A debt of a corps certain 
 cannot be paid by delivering another corps certain. 
 
 And a debt of wheat cannot be paid by delivery of wine or 
 eoal. (Laurent, 17, n. 601; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 272; 
 Demolombe, 28, nos. 28—30.) • 
 
 Debtor cannot injure rights of creditors. 
 
 In exercising this choice, the debtor cannot affect any right 
 which a creditor has. So if one of the debts is not due, and the 
 term was stipulated in favour of the creditor, the debtor cannot 
 impute the payment to this debt. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1579; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 273.) And if the debtor owes two 
 debts which are both due, and they are of unequal amount, one, 
 e.g., for L. E. 1,000, and one for L. E. 500, and he pays a sum 
 equal to the smaller debt, that is L. E. 500, he cannot oblige the 
 creditor to impute this to the debt for L. E. 1,000, for this 
 would be compelling the creditor to take a partial payment of a 
 debt, contrary to C. C. E. 168/231. 
 
 Exception to rule that debtor can make imputation. 
 
 An exception to this rule that the debtor can make an imputa- 
 tion at the time of payment is stated in the following article: — 
 Payments shall in the first instance be imputed to cost*, 
 ■interest and instalments, and afterwards to the principal sum 
 
 30 (2) 
 
468 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 due (C. C. E. 173/236.) The French Code says: The debtor 
 of a debt which bears interest or produces rent, cannot, without 
 the consent of the creditor, impute any payment which he makes 
 to the discharge of the capital in preference to the arrears of 
 interest or of rent. Any payment made on the capital and 
 interest, /'/if iehich is not entire, is imputed first upon the intej-est . 
 (C. C. F. 1254; Pau, 3 mars 1890, D. 91. 2. 117. See note by 
 M. de Loynes to Req. 8 juin 1901, D. 1907. 1. 473; Civ. 27 oct. 
 1908, D. 1909. 1. 60.) Interest comes before principal. The 
 rule does not apply to payments made in the course of the pro- 
 cedure of distribution. (C. A. Alex. 31 dec. 1918, B. L. J. 
 XXXI, 91.) Moreover, though the French Code does not ex- 
 pressly say so, it is universally agreed that if the creditor has 
 been put to expense in recovering his money, a partial payment is 
 imputed first to the expenses, second to interest, and third to 
 capital. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1580.) The 
 Egyptian Code makes this clear. 
 
 It may be agreed that payments made before the debt is due 
 shall be imputed to capital. (C. A. Alex. 26 nov. 1908, B. L. J. 
 XXI, 25.) 
 
 Imputation by the creditor. 
 
 By C. C. F. 1255: When a debtor of several debts has 
 accepted a receipt by which the creditor has imputed what he has 
 received in discharge specially of one of the debts, the debtor 
 cannot afterwards require the imputation to be made upon a 
 different debt, unless the debtor has been defrauded or taken by 
 surprise by the creditor. The Egyptian law is the same as to 
 this, though the code is silent. (C. A. Alex. 11 janv. 1900, 
 B. L. J. XII, 84.) 
 
 By taking without objection a receipt from the creditor in which 
 the latter states that he has imputed the payment to a certain 
 debt, the debtor is held to have assented to this imputation, and 
 he cannot challenge it except on such grounds as force, fraud, or 
 error. The French Code says: a moins qu'il n'y ail eu dot on 
 surprise de la part du creancier. And surprise is interpreted as 
 meaning a milder variety of fraud, in which it is not necessary 
 that there should have been artifices, or manoeuvres directed to 
 lead the debtor into error. B.-L. et Barde. 2, n. l-^So; Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 274. 
 
 A fortiori, the creditor is bound by the imputation which he 
 has made and which the debtor has accepted. He cannot after- 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 469 
 
 wards change his mind and seek to make another imputation. 
 (Deniolombe, 28, n. 36; Aubry et RaU, 5th cd. 4, p. 274, note 8; 
 C. A. Alex. 13 jnin 1916, B. h. J. XXVIII, 423.) When other 
 creditors may be prejudiced by the imputation, the creditor who 
 alleges that the imputation was made with the debtor's •consent, 
 must bring satisfactory proof of this fact. (C. A. Alex. '31 dec. 
 1918, B. L. J. XXXI, 88.) 
 
 Legal imputation. 
 
 When the debtor has not made any special imputation of a 
 payment, and has not, by taking a receipt, assented to an imputa- 
 tion made by the creditor, the law makes the imputation for 
 him. 
 
 By C. C. F. 1256; C. C. Q. 1161: When the receipt makes 
 no special imputation the payment must be imputed in discharge 
 of the debt actually, payable which the debtor had cd the tim,e 
 the greatest interest in paying. If of severed debts one alone be 
 actually payable the payment must be imputed in disci targe of 
 such debt, although it be less burdensome than those which are 
 not actually payable ; if the debts be of like nature, the imputation 
 is made upon the oldest. 
 
 All things being equal, it is made proportionate 1 y on ca"h. 
 
 These rules are reasonable, and correspond to the presumed 
 intention of the debtor when he makes the payment, and it is, 
 therefore, to be assumed that the Egyptian legislator meant to 
 retain them, though the Egyptian Code says merely that the 
 payment is imputed to the debt which the debtor has the most 
 interest in discharging. (C. C. E. 172/235. See C. A. Alex. 
 28 mars 1918, B. L. J. XXX, 319.) 
 
 It is a question of fact which debt is the most onerous for the 
 debtor. But, in general, a debt secured by a hypothec is more 
 onerous than a chirographic debt. (C. A. Alex. 14 juin 1916, 
 B. L. J. XXVIII, 428.) A debt bearing interest is more onerous 
 than a debt which does not bear interest, a debt for which a surety 
 has been given is more onerous than an unsecured debt, and so on. 
 (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 275, note 12; B.-L. et Barde, 2, 
 n. 1590.) But a debt in which the debtor is bound jointly and 
 severally with others is generally less onerous than a debt which 
 he owes alone, because in the latter case he has no recourse. 
 (Cass. 8 aoiit 1888, D. 89. 1. 283.) 
 
V 
 
 470 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Comparison with other laws. 
 
 The rule of imputation of payments being founded upon the 
 presumed intention of the debtor, it is natural to find very similar 
 provisions upon the subject in other laws. In the English law 
 the doctrine is called "appropriation of payments." (See Leake, 
 Contracts, 6th ed. p. 667; Halsbury, Laws of England, Con- 
 tracts, p. 449; Benjamin on Sale, 5th ed. p. 796.) The German 
 Code differs from the French law upon one point. If the debtor 
 has made no imputation, and there are several debts due, the 
 payment is imputed by law to the debt which offered the least 
 security for the creditor (art. 366). It is argued that this 
 corresponds best with the presumed intention of the parties. It is 
 presumed that the creditor if he refrains from suing for immediate 
 payment of the other debts does so because the most doubtful 
 debt has been paid. (See Note to the French translation.) 
 
 The Swiss Code applies this rule only when none of the debts- 
 is due: Si aucune des defies n'est echae, V imputation se fait 
 stir celle qui presente le moins de garanties pour le ereancier. 
 (Code Fed. Oblig. 87.) 
 
 Effect of the impossibility of finding the creditor in order to 
 
 pay him, or of the refusal by the creditor to take payment. 
 
 Tender and payment into court. 
 
 The creditor may be abroad, or have disappeared and have left 
 no one authorised to take payment. Or it may happen that the 
 creditor refuses to accept the payment that is offered to him. He 
 may say that the thing which was offered was not the thing which 
 was due; he may demand a larger sum than that which is offered: 
 or he may give some other reason for his refusal, or he may give- 
 no reason at all. The impossibility of finding the creditor, or 
 the refusal by the creditor to take the thing due may cause damage 
 to the debtor in a variety of ways. If the debt is a money-debt 
 he wants to put an end to the running of the interest. If he has 
 to deliver moveable things he wants to free himself from the 
 risk of having to take care of them, and, perhaps, to make room 
 in his warehouse for other goods, and the law must provide him 
 with some means of discharging his obligation, even if the creditor 
 refuses to accept the payment. The debtor who is prepared to 
 do his legal duty must not be prejudiced by the fact that the 
 creditor is in fault. The procedure which the law devises for this 
 purpose is what is called Tender, or Tender and Payment into 
 
 
 ■\Aj> 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 471 
 
 Court, and, in French, Offres reelles and Consignation. The 
 full discussion of the subject belongs to the law of procedure, and 
 the details are given in the Codes of Civil Procedure. (N. C. 
 C. P. 685—699; M. C. C. P. 773—787; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, 
 Traite de Procedure, 2nd ed. 7, n. 2712; Lusena Boy, Elements 
 de Procedure Civile et Commerciale Egyptienne, 3rd ed. 2, 
 p. 360.) 
 
 But the articles in the Codes of Procedure deal only with debts 
 of money or moveables. (See Trib. Civ. Lille, 7 juin 1905, D. 
 1906. 5. 15.) Provision must also be made for the eases of an 
 obligation to perform an act and an obligation to deliver an 
 immoveable. The subject is dealt with in the Egyptian Civil Code 
 in articles 174—176/237—239. 
 
 I will give first the case of the obligation to pay a sum of 
 money, or a specific thing-, and then the other cases. 
 
 Obligation to pay a sum of money or to deliver a specific 
 corporeal thing. 
 
 The Civil Code merely refers to the Code of Procedure: Never- 
 theless, ivhen the performance consists in a payment or in a de- 
 livery of moveables, the debtor is discharged by making a tender 
 in the manner prescribed by the Code of Procedure. (C. C. E. 
 175/238.) 
 
 This is the case for which the codes of procedure make careful 
 provision. (C. C. Pro. N. 685 seq.; C. C. Pro. M. 773 seq.) 
 This procedure consists, broadly speaking, in requiring the debtor: 
 
 (1) To make a formal offer by a bailiff of the sum of money 
 or the thing, the bailiff making a proces verbal of the offer, and 
 of the refusal of the creditor to accept it . A debtor is not liberated 
 by making an informal offer which the creditor refuses to accept. 
 If the creditor sues him and gets a judgment he will be entitled 
 to his costs, even though the debtor had made an informal offer 
 of the same amount as that which he is now condemned to pay. 
 (C. A. Alex. 7 fevr. 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 202. See the 
 common form of the proces verbal in Formulaire of Bairamoglou 
 et Eizzo, Formule 513.) 
 
 (2) To make a deposit of the money or the thing at the treasury 
 of the court, or, in certain cases, in the hands of a receiver 
 appointed by the court. 
 
 In France, the matter is dealt with partly in the Civil Code 
 
 
 
 
472 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 and partly in the Code of Civil Procedure. (C. C. F. 1257 seq.; 
 C. C. P. 812 seq.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code differs in language from the French Code. 
 The details belong to the law of procedure, but the following 
 points may be noticed: — 
 
 (1) The procedure consists of two stages: (a) an offer or off res 
 reelles, and (b) a payment into court or consignation. It is 
 essential that the payment should have been preceded by the offer. 
 (C. A. Alex. 6 mai 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 372; C. A. Alex. 
 26 nov. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 50; Cass. 17 dec. 1894, D. 95. 
 1.90.) 
 
 (2) By an offer is meant an actual tender, not a mere promise 
 to deliver, saving what is said later as to tender of a specific 
 thing which is undeliverable at the domicile. 
 
 (3) When the debt is of money, the tender must be made in 
 coin which is part of the currency, or is, as it is often called, a. 
 "legal tender." (Decree, 14 nov. 1885, Gelat, 3, p. 495.) But 
 this has been changed in Egypt by the Decree of 2 Aug. 1914, 
 which makes notes of the National Bank of Egypt "legal tender."' 
 
 Silver money is only legal tender up to P. T. 200 and bronze 
 or nickel up to P. T. 10. 
 
 (4) The tender must be unconditional. A conditional tender 
 is not equivalent to a payment; it is a mere proposal which the 
 creditor can accept or not. (C. A. Alex. 14 fevr. 1895, B. L. J. 
 VII, 136; C. A. Alex. 6 mai 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 372; C. A. 
 Alex. 10 dec. 1914, B. L. J. XXVII, 58.) A tender is not 
 conditional merely because the debtor declares that the tender is 
 made subject to his getting a discharge. (Req. 20 juin 1899, 
 D. 99. 1. 591; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, Traite de Procedwe 
 Civile, 2nd ed. 7, n. 2715.) 
 
 (5) There are special rules as to the case of specific corporeal 
 things: 
 
 The tender of a specific corporeal thing which cannot be 
 delivered at the domicile of the creditor can be made by a simple 
 summons to take delivery. 
 
 The debtor has the right to obtain from the court the appoint- 
 ment of a receiver for the specific corporeal thing tendered. 
 (C. C. Pro. E. 698, 699/786, 787.) 
 
 The words " cannot be delivered at the domicile of the creditor " 
 cover, no doubt, the case when, although it is not physically 
 impossible to make the delivery, such a delivery would not be a 
 reasonable way of satisfying the obligation. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 473 
 
 If the duty of the debtor was to deliver a locomotive engine, 
 or some other article difficult of transport and not intended to be 
 installed in the domicile, the law is not so absurd as to oblige 
 the debtor to convey it to the creditor's domicile. He can call 
 upon the creditor to take delivery of it where it is, and failing- 
 this, can ask the court to appoint a receiver to take charge of it, 
 or apply for authority to get it sold by the bailiff and the price 
 deposited in the caisse. (See C. A. Alex. 4 avr. 1900, B. L. J. 
 XII, 190. Cf. C. C. F. 1264.) 
 
 (6) A tender followed by the payment into court, and signi- 
 fication to the creditor, if he is absent, liberates the debtor from 
 the date of the consignation when it is established that the tender 
 was rendered necessary by the unjustifiable refusal of the creditor 
 to receive the payment. (See Cass. 3 dec. 1912, D. 1913. 5. 42; 
 Cass. 27 mars 1911, D. 1915. 1. 97, note by M. Cezar-Bru.) 
 
 (7) But the validity of a tender and payment into court depends 
 upon the following conditions: — 
 
 The tender must be to a person to whom payment could validly 
 be made, and it must be by a person capable of making a payment, 
 for, otherwise, the creditor who gets payment may be liable to an 
 action in repetition. The tender must be in full, just as payment 
 cannot be in part, and the debt must be due, unless the term is 
 in favour merely of the debtor, in which case he can waive the 
 benefit of the term. If the debt is subject to a condition which 
 has not been fulfilled, the creditor cannot be compelled to take 
 payment, and, therefore, a tender to him is not valid, because 
 if he took payment and the condition afterwards failed, he would 
 be liable in an action for restitution of what he had got. (C. C. F. 
 1258.) 
 
 The French Code contains very jn-ecise rules as to the offres 
 reelles. 
 
 Pour que les offres reelles soient valables, il faut : 
 
 Qu'elles soient de la totalite de la somme exigible, des arrerages 
 ou interets dus, des frais liquides, et d'une somme pour les fra&s 
 non liquides, sauf a la parfaire. (C. C. F. art. 1258.) 
 
 The rules must be literally complied with. (See Cass. 17 fevr. 
 1908, S. 1908. 1. 192; Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, 2nd ed. 7, 
 n. 2715.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is less strict: 
 
 .4 debtor who wishes to discharge himself shall cause the 
 thing or the sum, which he alleges to be owing jrom him, — la 
 chose ou la somme quit pretend devoir — to be tendered by a 
 
474 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 bailiff, who sJiall draw up a proces-verbal of such tender. (C. C. 
 C. Pr. 685/773.) 
 
 And it has been held: 
 
 L'insuffisance tres modique d'un depot ne saurait en detruire 
 Veffet liber atoire, jusqu'a due concurrence. (C. A. Alex. 18 
 janv. 1893, B. L. J. V, 101.) 
 
 JJne off re reelle, inferieure d'une somme minime a la somme 
 reellement due, par suite d'une simple omission, ne saurait, par 
 cela seul, perdre son caractere liber atoire. (C. A. Alex. 21 dec. 
 1893, B. L. J. VI, 77.) 
 
 The practice is to offer: 
 
 (1) A sum for the principal; 
 
 (2) A sum for the interest; 
 
 (3) A sum for the costs. (See the Formulaire of MM. Baira- 
 moglou et Rizzo, Formule 513.) 
 
 Tender at bar of court. 
 
 Tenders may be made at the bar of the court, without further 
 formalitij. The thing or sum tendered shall be handed to the 
 registrar, who shall deposit it, provided it is not withdrawn by 
 the creditor. (C C. Pr. E. 697/785.) 
 
 The French law is the same, though there is no text. (Gar- 
 sonnet et Cezar-Bru, Traite de Procedure, 7, n. 2716; Aubry 
 et Rau. 5th ed. 4, p. 318, note 9.) 
 
 Action to have tender declared valid. 
 
 The debtor who wants to be certain that he has done all that 
 can be required of him, and that all has been regularly done, 
 must bring a claim to have the tender declared valid. (C. C. E. 
 Pro 695/783.) 
 
 Obligation to do or not to do. 
 
 The Egyptian Civil Code says: A person under an obliga- 
 tion to perform an act is not discharged ipso facto by a tender of 
 performance, but he has a right of recourse against the creditor 
 for the damage resulting to him from the rejection thereof at the 
 time of tender. (C. C. E. 174/237.) The code does not attempt 
 to indicate in what way a debtor whose obligation is to perform 
 an act may make what is equivalent to a tender. This depends 
 upon the nature of the obligation. If the performance cannot 
 be made without the concurrence of the creditor, the debtor can 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 475' 
 
 call upon him to lend his concurrence at a time and place stated, 
 and, if he does not then appear, the debtor can sue for dissolution 
 of the contract and for damages, unless the creditor prefers to 
 lend his co-operation to the performance. This procedure might 
 be followed, for instance, in such a case as where the contract was 
 to paint a portrait, and the creditor refused to sit for it. (Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, Oblig.. 2, n. 1626; Demolombe, 28, n. 180. 
 See Trib. Civ. Lille, 7 juin 1895, D. 1906. 5. 15.) 
 
 Obligation to deliver an immoveable. 
 
 The Civil Code says: A discharge can be obtained from art 
 obligation to deliver cm immoveable by procuring the appoint- 
 ment of a judici-al receiver by a judgment given in a contested 
 suit or in a suit in ivhich the creditor has been sumynmied. 
 (C. C. E. 176/239.) Actual delivery of an immoveable is out 
 of the question and something equivalent has to be found. The 
 appointment of a judicial receiver or sequestrator whose duty it 
 is to take charge of the immoveable, and to receive the revenues 
 for the benefit of the creditor, is a procedure which meets the 
 requirements of the case. 
 
 The French law is the same, though there is no express provi- 
 sion in the code. (B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1624; Garsonnet 
 et Cezar-Bru, Traite de Procedure, 2nd ed. 7, n. 2720. See 
 C. C. F. 1961, al.3.) 
 
 Obligation to deliver an indeterminate thing. 
 
 Neither the Egyptian nor the French codes deal with this case, 
 and it is not free from difficulty. According to some French 
 authorities, the fact that the codes provide for tender without 
 actual delivery only in the case of specific corporeal things, shows 
 that no such practice is permissible in other cases. If the debt 
 were, for example, to deliver 1,000 bushels of corn or 100 barrels 
 of wine, to be taken in both cases from a 'larger mass, the only 
 way in which the debtor could make a tender would be by carting 
 the goods to the creditor's domicile and back again. 
 
 For, if the debtor were to separate the goods and then call on 
 the creditor to take delivery he would be changing the character 
 of his debt, and transforming it into an obligation to deliver a 
 specific thing. (B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1625; Laurent, 18, n. 191 .) 
 
 But this seems a needlessly strict interpretation. The code 
 
476 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 is silent, as to the case, but that is no reason why we may not 
 extend by analogy the rule stated as to the specific thing. 
 
 It would be a valid offer if the debtor called upon the creditor 
 to be present at a stated time and place in order to see th& 
 .separation made and to take delivery. (Garsonnet et Cezar-Bru, 
 Traite de Procedure, 7, n. 2720; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 325; 
 Demolombe, 28, n. 176.) 
 
 And, probably, it would be competent to ask the court to appoint 
 an expert to see the individualisation made, failing the debtor's 
 concurrence. (See C. A. Alex, 4 avr. 1900, B. L. J. XII, 190.) 
 
 (2) Dissolution by the performance of the obligation 
 becoming impossible. 
 
 This is the second mode of extinction enumerated in the Egyp- 
 tian Code. 
 
 The general rules upon this subject have been explained under 
 the head of force majeure. (Supra, p. 316.) -The case which 
 remains to consider is that which is dealt with in the French Code 
 under the head de la perte de la chose due. (C. C. F. 1302 seq.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no special article on this point. It 
 treats it as a case falling under the general rule. Obligations 
 are extinguished by dissolution, when, after they have come into 
 existence, performance of them has become impossible. If per- 
 formance has become impossible through the fault of the debtor, 
 or if the impossibility has arisen while the debtor is in default 
 as regards execution, he is liable for damages. (C. C. E. 177, 
 178 240, 241.) But the only kind of impossibility we are now 
 considering is that which arises from the perishing of a specific 
 thing. 
 
 The obligation in this case cannot be performed on account of 
 the destruction of the specific thing which the debtor undertook 
 to deliver. An obligation to deliver something in genere, for 
 example, so many bushels of wheat, can hardly be extinguished 
 in this way: Genus nunquam peril. If I sell 1,000 bushels of 
 wheat, and all my wheat is destroyed, I can get other bushels 
 elsewhere. The contract is not to deliver any particular bushels; 
 if those which I had in my warehouse at the time of the contract 
 have perished, I can satisfy the obligation by procuring other 
 bushels. Demolombe, 28, n. 751; Laurent, 18, n. 515: Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 408, note 7; B.-L. et Bardo, 3, n. 1917. 
 See Rev. Trim. 1917, p. 151.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 477 
 
 But, if I undertake to deliver a certain specific thing and it 
 perishes, I can never fulfil the obligation at all. I may deliver 
 something of equal value, but that would not be to fulfil the 
 obligation. If I buy a piano and it perishes before delivery, 
 the seller cannot say to me: " I will give you another piano 
 instead." When the obligation is to deliver a certain specific 
 thing, the law regards this obligation as always made subject to 
 the implied condition that the thing shall be in existence at the 
 time of payment. It might seem just that if the seller from no. 
 fault of his cannot deliver the thing sold, the bargain should be 
 off altogether, and the buyer should not bo bound to pay the 
 price. And the Egyptian law is in this sense, as will be explained 
 later. 
 
 But this is not the view which the French law takes. The 
 contract is completed by consent, and each party comes under 
 distinct obligations, the seller to make delivery, the buyer to pay 
 the price. The seller is freed from his obligation by the super- 
 vening impossibility of performance, if that impossibility is not 
 due to any fault on his part, and if he was not in default to deliver.. 
 But, though this destruction of the thing extinguishes his obliga- 
 tion, it does not extinguish the entirely separate obligation of 
 the buyer to pay the price. This was the rule of the Roman law 
 and of the old French law, although under them the buyer did not 
 become the owner of the thing by the effect of the contract, but 
 only when it was delivered. (Inst. 3. 23. 3; Girard, Manuel, 
 5th ed. 547; Pothier, Vente, n. 307.) 
 
 For, in spite. of this, after the contract the thing lay at the 
 buyer's risk, though he was not its owner. In the modern law 
 the rule that the loss is that of the buyer is more easily justified 
 as an application of the principle r.es petit domino, that is, if a 
 thing perishes its owner must bear the loss. (Guillouard, Vente,. 
 1, n. 246, 1; Pand. Frang. Oblig. n. 6247; D. N. C. C. art. 1624, 
 nos. 1 seq.) The English law is the same, except when delivery has 
 been delayed by fault. "Unless otherwise agreed, the goods 
 remain at the seller's risk until the property therein is transferred 
 to the buyer, but when the property therein is transferred to the 
 buyer, the goods are at the buyer's risk whether delivery has been 
 made or not." (Sale of Goods Act, 1893 (56 & 57 Vict. c. 71), 
 s. 20; Benjamin on Sale, 5th ed. 404; Williston on Sales of 
 Goods, s. 300.) 
 
-478 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Contract may imply that risk was to be on seller. 
 
 But under the French law, in the sale of a thing to be delivered 
 
 : at a future date, the court may find in the circumstances of the 
 contract evidence of the intention to make the sale subject to the 
 implied condition that the thing should be' in existence at that 
 
 vdate. The courts in France are reluctant to find a buyer liable 
 for the price when the seller cannot deliver the thing, and in 
 recent cases they have been rather astute in reading such implied 
 
 ■ conditions into the contract. For example, in the sale of a foal 
 to be delivered when weaned, it was held to be an implied con- 
 dition that the foal should be alive at the time fixed for delivery. 
 (Rennes, 24 dec. 1906, S. 1907. 2. 164. Cf . Cass. 8 janv. 1906, 
 
 . S. 1906. 1. 176; and see Rev. Trim. 1907, 819.) 
 
 The loss of thing due an instance of impossibility of 
 performance. 
 
 According to the French Code: When the certain specific thing 
 which is the object of an obligation perishes, or is put extra 
 commerciwn, or is lost in such a way that its existence is abso- 
 lutely unknown, the obligation is extinguished if the thing 
 perished or was lost without the fault of the debtor and before 
 he was in default. It is also extinguished although the debtor be 
 in default if the thing would equally have perished in the posses- 
 sion of the creditor, unless the debtor has expressly bound himself 
 for fortuitous events. 
 
 The debtor must prove the fortuitous event which he alleges. 
 In whatever way a thing stolen has perished or has been lost, its loss 
 does not discharge him who stole the thing from the obligation 
 to pay its value." (C. C. F. 1302; C. C. Q. 1200; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 3, n. 1916; Req. 20 mars 1912, D. 1913. 1. 247.) All 
 this is correct as a statement of Egyptian law. 
 
 In the case where the obligation is to deliver a certain number 
 'or quantity of things it may be specified that they are to be 
 taken from the stock of the seller, or that they are at present lying 
 in his warehouse. In such a case if the whole stock were to perish, 
 the seller might maintain that his obligation was extinguished 
 by the impossibility of performance. But even here the pre- 
 sumption is against him. It is presumed that the statement of 
 the place where the goods were was merely by way of description, 
 and that it was not intended as limiting the oblisration of the 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 479 
 
 seller to deliver from that stock only. It is a question of inter- 
 pretation. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 659; Baudry-Lacant. et .Barde, 
 Oblig. 3, n. 1917.) 
 
 It is according to the general rules of evidence that the debtor 
 who pleads that he has been released from his obligation to deliver 
 should be under the necessity of making proof of all that is 
 necessary to support his plea. 
 
 A fortuitous event by definition is one which it was impossible 
 to resist, and illustrations have been given earlier of the meaning 
 of this term. (Supra, pp. 287 seq.) So, it is not enough for the 
 debtor to allege that the thing which he bound himself to deliver 
 has been destroyed by fire or has been stolen, for it might have been 
 possible for him to prevent its loss in this way. He must prove in 
 addition that he could not prevent the accident. (Req. 9 mai 1911, 
 D. 1912. 1. 401.) But " impossibility ".mustbe taken in a reason- 
 able sense. If all ordinary precautions to prevent the accident 
 were taken, its occurrence will be regarded as one which it was 
 impossible to prevent. This has been held in many cases both 
 as to fire and as to theft. (See Cass. 16 mai 1904, D. 1905. 1. 
 189, and supra, pp. 297, 299, 303.) A man who leaves L. E. 
 1,000 in an open bag in his room while he goes to lunch can 
 hardly say, if it disappears, that this was due to a fortuitous 
 event . 
 
 The last paragraph of the article in the French Code states the 
 rule of exceptional severity based on disfavour to thieves. But 
 the rule is one which follows from general principles. 
 
 The thief, or the guilty receiver, must pay the value of the 
 thing, although it has disappeared by fortuitous event. He cannot 
 say he was free from fault, because it was through his fault that 
 the thing came into his possession. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 664; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1925.) 
 
 Application of rule against unjust enrichment. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says that when the correlative obligations 
 are extinguished this is to be without prejudice to the right of 
 indemnity, if any, due from the respective parties for any benefit 
 acquired without cause. (C. C. E. 179/242.) The Quebec 
 Code is more full: When the performance of an obligation to 
 do has become impossible without any act or fault of the debtor 
 and before he is in default the obligcdion is extinguished and 
 both parties are liberated; but if the obligation be beneficially 
 
 4 
 
480 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 performed in port, the creditor is hound to the extent of the 
 benefit actual/// received by him. (C. C. Q. 1202.) 
 
 This is an important instance of the application of the general 
 principle against allowing an unjust enrichment which has been 
 fully explained earlier. (Supra, pp. 140 seq., 163 seq.) 
 
 In regard to the obligation to do or not to do, the two parties 
 are considered as having entered into correlative obligations. If 
 the work cannot be done the price does not need to be paid. If a 
 painter undertakes to paint a picture and, before he has done so, 
 he becomes blind, he is not bound to pay damages, and neither is 
 the client bound to pay for the picture. In, some cases an un- 
 finished work may be of value, and, in that case, a proportion of 
 the price must be paid corresponding to the value of the work 
 done. This is upon the general principle against unjust enrich- 
 ment which is explained under the head of quasi-contracts. In 
 the case of the picture if the artist had begun it, and had then 
 become blind, probably nothing would have to be paid, because 
 the unfinished picture would not be of any value. (Supra, p. 317. 
 Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1916.) 
 
 Theory of risk in the Egyptian law. 
 
 The Egyptian law is not the same as the French law upon the 
 important matter of the risk in the case of synallagmatic con- 
 tracts. As to unilateral contracts there is no difficulty. 
 
 There is here only one obligation, and if it is impossible to 
 execute it there is an end of the matter. For instance, if I deposit 
 my box of silver in your care, and it is lost by a fortuitous event,, 
 your obligation to deliver it is extinguished and the contract 
 comes to an end altogether. 
 
 But in a synallagmatic contract there are correlative obliga- 
 tions, and logically speaking, it is quite possible that one of them 
 should survive the extinction of the other. In the French law we 
 have seen that this is so in the case of sale; the purchaser is still 
 bound to pay the price although the obligation of the seller to 
 deliver the thing has been extinguished by fortuitous event. 
 (Supra, p. 477.) 
 
 This is stated in C. C. F. 1138. This article is badly expressed 
 and there is controvorsv with regard to its meaning: 
 
 L' obligation de timer la chose est parfaite par le seul consente- 
 ment des parties contractantes. 
 
 EJJr rend le creancier proprietaire et met la chose d ses risque? 
 
 I 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 481 
 
 des Vinstant ou elle a du etre livree, encore que la tradition rten 
 ait point ete faite, a moins que le debiteur ne soit en demeure de 
 la livrer ; auquel cas la chose reste aux risques de ce dernier. 
 
 The singular expression — des Vinstant ou elle a dil etre livree 
 — might very naturally mean that if it had been agreed that 
 the thing was not to be delivered for a certain period the risk 
 should not pass to the creditor until this period had arrived, but 
 from the so-called " preliminary works," that is the compilations 
 giving the reports and discussions of the commissions which pre- 
 pared the Code Napoleon, we know that this was not what was 
 meant. The expression means that the thing is at the risk of 
 the creditor from the time at which he acquires an action to sue 
 for its delivery. (Fenet, 14, p. 113; Locre, 14, p. 145, in fine, 
 n. 6; Baudry-Lacantineiie et Barde, Oblig. 1, n. 366.) 
 
 But suppose the parties have agreed in their contract that the 
 property is not to pass until delivery, who is to bear the risk then? 
 Upon this there is controversy. Demolombe and others say that 
 we should follow the principle of the Roman law under which, 
 the risk passed to the buyer by the contract, though the property 
 did not pass until delivery. (Demolombe, 24, n. 424; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 1, n. 424.) 
 
 Planiol and others contend" that the French Code means to lay 
 down the principle res per it domino. If, under the contract, the 
 purchaser is not the owner the risk remains with the seller. (2, 
 n. 1347.) Such an agreement is not common and the question 
 is not of much practical importance. 
 
 In Egyptian law the contract has the effect of transferring the 
 propertj', but the risk does not pass until delivery. 
 
 This was the theory of the Mohammedan law which the Egyp- 
 tian legislator meant to preserve. (Kadri Pacha, Statut reel, 
 No. 460.) 
 
 It is clearly stated as regards sale in C. C. E. 297/371: // 
 the thing sold perishes before delivery, even ivithout fault or 
 negligence on the part of the vendor, the sale shall be dissol/cvd 
 and the price, if necessary, refunded, unless the purchaser is in 
 default as regards taking delivery, resulting from formal demand 
 by summons or other equivalent process, or from the terms of the 
 agreement itself. 
 
 This clear statement must prevail over the more obscure lan- 
 guage of C. C. E. (266/336, which says that sale, "according to 
 circumstances," throws the risk of the thing sold upon the pur- 
 chaser. By "according to circumstances" we must hero under- 
 
 w. — vol. n. 31 
 
 
482 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 stand the cases when the purchaser is in default to take delivery, 
 or where under the terms of the contract the risk was to be upon 
 him, or when by its terms the delivery was to be at the same time 
 as the contract. And the Egyptian law applies the same rule as 
 to the risk in the case of the partial loss or deterioration of a thing. 
 (C. C. E. 298/372.) 
 
 This principle of the Egyptian law of sale is not peculiar to 
 that contract. The code lays down the general rule: When an 
 obligation is dissolved in consequence of impossibility of perform- 
 ance the correlative obligations are in like manner dissolved. 
 (C. C. E. 179/242.) 
 
 This is the general rule of the French law also, though it does 
 not apply in the case of the obligation to transfer a specific thing, 
 and it is the only rule which is consistent with the theory of 
 synallagmatic contracts. The two obligations depend upon each 
 other. Each of them is conditional upon the fulfilment of the 
 other, and it is inequitable to require the one party to perform 
 when the other party cannot perform on his side. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 1336. See supra, p. 316.) 
 
 The difference between the French and Egyptian law is that 
 the French law makes 6ale and the contracts assimilated to sale 
 exceptions to this general rule, whereas the Egyptian law applies 
 the same rule to all synallagmatic contracts. 
 
 Unfortunately, however, the Egyptian Code is not well drawn, 
 and some articles are inconsistent with the principle which the 
 legislator means to adopt. It is hard to see, for example, why 
 when goods are sold by weight, number, or measure, and they 
 have been weighed, counted, or measured, as the case niay be, the 
 risk should then pass to the purchaser. (C. C. E. 241/307.) 
 
 The Egyptian legislator seems in this article to have copied 
 C. C. F. 1585 without remembering that he had elsewhere adopted 
 a different principle from that of the French Code. And the; 
 article C. C. E. 424/516 is also inconsistent but does not concern 
 us. (See Grandmoulin, Contrats, n. 58; De Hults, Rep. vo. 
 Risques, n. 12; vo. Vente, n. 117; Halton, 2, p. 26.) 
 
 (3) Novation. 
 
 This is the third mode of extinction. 
 
 The Egyptian Code defines novation thus: Novatio?i extin- 
 guishes an obligation and establishes a new obligation which re- 
 places the former. It results from a contract. (C. C. E. 
 
 186/249.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 483 
 
 Novation is the substitution of a new obligation for an old one, 
 and it presupposes that the old debt is extinguished. 
 
 For this reason novation comes more naturally immediately 
 after payment, as it does in the French Code, than after release, 
 as in the Egyptian Code. (C. C. F. 1234; C. C. E. 158/221.) 
 The substitution of the new debt which is involved in novation 
 is equivalent to a payment of the old debt. 
 
 And what is called elation en paiement is in fact an example 
 of novation. This means that the creditor voluntarily accepts 
 another prestation in place of that which had been promised. If 
 I owe you L. E. 20, and you agree to accept my camel instead, 
 there has been a new debt created, viz., the debt to pay the camel, 
 though the debt was paid t as soon as it was made by my delivering 
 the camel. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 258, note 1; Planiol, 2, 
 n. 523; Demolombe, 27, n. 230.) 
 
 Novation is subject to five conditions: — 
 
 (1) The existence of an old debt; 
 
 (2) The creation of a new debt; 
 
 (3) A new element, making a difference between the new debt 
 and the old one, so that the new one is not a mere acknowledgment 
 of the old one; 
 
 (4) The intention to novate, and 
 
 (5) The capacity of parties. 
 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1690; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 348.) 
 
 The novation may take three forms: — 
 
 (1) A change of the object of the debt; 
 
 (2) A change of the debtor; and 
 
 (3) A change of the creditor. 
 
 These three varieties are stated in C. C. E. 187/251. 
 Novation takes place: — 
 
 (1) When the creditor and the debtor agree to substitute a new 
 obligation for the original obligation which is extinguished, or to 
 change the consideration of the original obligation ; 
 
 (2) When the creditor and a third person agree that the latter 
 shall become the debtor in place of the original debtor, who is 
 discharged without his consent being necessary, or when the debtor 
 has procured the acceptance by the creditor of a third person as 
 his debtor, such third person consenting to pay in his stead ; 
 
 (3) When the creditor and the debtor agree that the latter 
 shall perform the obligation for the benefit of a third person umo 
 consents thereto. 
 
 
 y^Uwvvo (1 
 
 irl 
 
484 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (1) Simple novation. 
 
 As an example of the first kind, if I owe yon a hundred 
 bushels of wheat, and we afterwards agree that instead of the 
 wheat I shall owe you a sum of money, there is novation by the 
 change of the object of the debt. 
 
 This is the simplest kind, and may be called novation simpli- 
 citer. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 582.) 
 
 It is also frequently called objective novation in contradis- 
 tinction to the kinds of novation in which one Of the parties is 
 changed. These are known as varieties of subjective novation. 
 (Aubry et Ran, 5th ed. 4, p. 346; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1697.) 
 
 (2) Delegation. 
 
 The second kind of novation is that in which there is the 
 intervention of a new debtor; I owe you "L. E. 1,000, and I get 
 you to release me and to accept Peter in my place. In this case 
 I am said to delegate Peter, and this variety of novation ia 
 specially called delegation. It cannot be effected, of course, with- 
 out the consent of the creditor and also of the debtor who is 
 delegated, for I cannot make Peter a debtor in a contract against 
 his will. (Dig. 46. 2. 11; Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. 700; Pothier, 
 Oblig. n. 600; C. C. F. 1275. See Douai, 13 nov. 1909, D. 
 1913. 2. 57.) 
 
 Delegation will be more fully explained later. 
 
 Expromission. 
 
 There is, however, another form of novation which likewise 
 falls under (2") and is known by the name expromissio. 
 
 This occurs, for example, when I owe you L. E. 1,000, and 
 another person comes forward spontaneously and without my re- 
 questing him to do so, and says to my creditor, "if you will 
 discharge your debtor I will become bound in his place," and the 
 creditor agrees to the substitution. Novation of this kind is 
 specially called expromissio. In this case, my consent is not 
 necessary, as the law makes the natural assumption that a debtor 
 is not likely to object to his debt being paid. (Pothier, Oblig. 
 nos. 583, 598; Aubry et Rail, 5th ed. 4, p. 347; B.-L. et 
 Barde, 3, n. 1715; C. A. Alex. 23 dec. 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 
 72.) 
 
 Novation by the substitution of a new debtor may be effected 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 485 
 
 without the concurrence of the former one. Just as a third party 
 can pay a debt without the consent of the debtor, so he may extin- 
 guish the debt of another by novation. (C. C. E. L87 251; 
 
 C. C. F. 1274.) 
 
 The effects of delegation will be stated later. 
 
 (3) Novation by change of creditor. 
 
 This requires the consent of all three parties; the old creditor, 
 the debtor and the new creditor. As the old creditor has to 
 renounce his claim it is natural that this can be done only by his 
 consent. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 351 ; Nancy, 21 fevr. 1877, 
 
 D. 78. 2. 14.) 
 
 There must be a clear declaration by the creditor of his intention 
 to renounce. The mere indication by the creditor of a person who 
 is to take payment for him is not novation. Such a person is 
 said to be adjectus solutionis gratia. (Dig. 46. 3. 95. 5. See 
 Cass. 11 janv. 1893, D. 95. 1. 179; B.-L. et Barde, OUig. 3, 
 n. 1725.) As to the consent of the debtor, it is required because 
 he is becoming bound to pay a new debt. He may lose by the 
 change of creditor the benefit of a defence which he had against, 
 the former creditor. (Colin et Capibant, 2, p. 103.) This form 
 of novation is not common in practice. It is generally more con- 
 venient and safer to make an assignment of the debt. (See 
 Laurent, 18, n. 299.) 
 
 Parties to novation must be capable. 
 
 The French Code says: — 
 
 Novation can be effected only between persons capable of 
 contracting. (C. C. F. 1272; C. C. Q. 1170.) 
 
 Novation extinguishes an obligation and the creditor who agrees 
 to novate renounces his right to sue on the old debt. It is, there- 
 fore, equivalent to an alienation, and can only be effected by a 
 person who has the right to alienate. Accordingly, a joint and 
 several creditor cannot novate a debt due to the creditors jointly 
 and severally except so far as concerns his share. {Supra, p. 406; 
 B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1728; 2, n. 1156; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 352.) 
 
 A person may be entitled to receive payment of the obligation, 
 and may yet be unable to novate it, for novation is an alienation. 
 (Demolombe, 28, n. 263; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1727.) Further, 
 the person who becomes liable for the new debt which is sub- 
 stituted for the old one must have the capacity to bind himself. 
 
486 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 But if the new obligation is voidable at his instance the novation 
 is good, unless and until he brings an action to have it set aside.. 
 If he does so, then, according -to the view of most authorities, the 
 novation is annulled, and the former obligation revives, because 
 the intention was that it should only be cancelled by the substitu- 
 tion of a second valid obligation. The creditor did not renounce 
 his old claim purely and simply. He made the renunciatiota 
 subject to the implied condition that the new debt should 'be 
 substituted, and if this new debt is annulled, the creditor must 
 be restored to his right to claim the old debt. (Demolombe, 28, 
 n. 252; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1696; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 352; D. N. C. C, art. 1271, n. 72.) 
 
 There are some dissentients. (Larombiere, on art. 1272, n. 2. 
 See D. N. C. C. art. 1271, n. 72.) 
 
 Novation not presumed. 
 
 The French Code says expressly: — 
 
 " Novation is not presumed. The intention to effect novation 
 must result clearly from the act." The Egyptian law is the 
 same, though the code is silent. (C. C. F. 1273; Cass. 8 aoiit 
 1900, D. 1905. 1. 262; C. A. Alex. 23 nov. 1911, B. L. J. 
 XXIV, 15; C. A. Alex. 23 dec. 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 72; 
 
 C. A. Alex. 19 avril 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 259.) When the 
 novation involves a renunciation by the creditor of his claim, this 
 is according to the general rule that there is a presumption against 
 a man renouncing any right which he has. When the novation 
 implies the assumption by a new debtor of the obligation of the 
 old debtor, there is likewise a presumption against this. (Douai, 
 13 nov. 1909, D. 1913. 2. 57.) So, where the proof is contra- 
 dictory, and the court is not satisfied as to the intention to novate, 
 the decision will be against it. But no sacramental terms are 
 prescribed; and the courts may in civil matters infer the inten- 
 tion to novate from presumptions if there is a commencement of 
 proof in writing. (Req. 27 nov. 1893, D. 94. 1. 60; Cass. 
 8 aout 1900, S. 1903. 1. 46, and the note; Req. 28 dec. 1908,- 
 
 D. 1909. 1. 214; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 354; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1273, n. 12; C. A. Alex. 22 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 
 167: C. A. Alex. 30 janv. 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 155.^ And 
 in commercial matters no commencement of proof in writing is 
 required. 
 
 Tin- modification of an existing obligation is not novation. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 487 
 
 It must be clear that the intention was to extinguish the old debt. 
 So there is no novation if the creditor merely stipulates that the 
 debtor shall give him a security for a debt previously unsecured, 
 or, on the other hand, if the creditor renounces a security which 
 he already holds. (Limoges, 15 juin 1898, S. 1901. 2. 134. 
 Cf. Cass. 13 janv. 1903, S. 1909. 1. 397; Cass. 28 juin 1904, 
 S. 1909. 1. 194; C. A. Alex. 15 juin 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 
 433; C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 118; C. A. 
 Alex. 26 avril 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 282; C. A. Alex. 23 mars 
 1910, B. L. J. XXII, 206.) 
 
 So in many cases it has been held that where a debtor wh,ose 
 debt is a simple contract debt, subsequently gives to his creditor 
 a bill or a promissory note, this does not effect novation unless 
 there is something which clearly shows that this was intended, 
 (C. A. Alex. 23 nov. 1911, B. L. J. XXIV, 15; C. A. Alex. 
 28 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 187; Req. 5 aout 1878, D. 79. 
 1. 71; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1732.) 
 
 The importance of this rule is generally in regard to prescrip- 
 tion. If there is no novation the creditor retains his right to sue 
 on the old debt, which may be a debt which prescribes only in 
 fifteen years. The action on the bill prescribes in five years. 
 (C. Comm. E. 194/201.) And, therefore, though the bill or 
 note may have prescribed by five years, the creditor still has his 
 remedy if he can prove the debt, whereas if there had been nova- 
 tion his right of action would have been lost after five years from 
 the date when the bill was due. (C. A. Alex. 22 mars 1893, 
 B. L. J. V, 182; C. A. Alex. 5 mai 1898, B. L. J. X, 264.J 
 Upon similar grounds it is held that the renewal of a bill does 
 not effect novation unless the intention to do so is apparent. 
 (Laurent, 18, n. 292; Toulouse, 8 mai 1888, D. 89. 2. 208.) 
 
 A fortiori, the granting of a delay for payment or the pro- 
 longation of the term fixed does not import novation. (C. A. 
 Alex. 23 dec. 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 72; C. A. Alex. 13 avril 
 1916, B.L.J. XXVIII, 254; C. A. Alex. 23 mars 1910, B.L.J. 
 XXII, 206.) And the substitution of an official document as 
 proof of the debt in place of a private writing is not inconsistent 
 with the keeping alive of the old debt. (C. A. Alex. 13 avril 
 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 254.) 
 
 The rule of law that novation is not presumed does not alter 
 the general rules as to proof. So it has been held that proof by 
 testimony is not admissible tending to prove in contradiction of 
 a document the novation of a debt exceeding P. T. 1,000. (C. A. 
 
488 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Alex. 27 mai 1909, B. L. J. XXI, 364.) Novation of a com- 
 mercial debt may be proved by testimony irrespective of the 
 amount. (Cass. 4 janv. 1888, D. 88. 1. 37; Baudry-Lacant. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1733.) 
 
 Must be valid debt to novate. 
 
 There cannot be any novation unless there is a valid debt to 
 begin with. Accordingly, if the original debt was null, for 
 instance, as having an illegal cause, or if it had been extinguished 
 in any way, it cannot be novated. (Pothier, Oblig. nos. 585 — 
 586.) But there may be a novation of a natural obligation, and 
 it may be turned into a civil one by novation. For novation, like 
 payment, amounts to a voluntary acknowledgment by the debtor 
 of the debt, and may indicate his intention to make it a civil debt. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 2, n. 1678.) This question 
 has been considered earlier in speaking of the effects of a natural 
 obligation. (Supra, I, p. 36.) 
 
 New debt must be substituted. 
 
 It is indispensable that there is a new debt created to come in 
 place of the old one. For otherwise the payment of the old debt 
 simply puts an end to it, and there is no substitution. (B.-L. 
 et Barde, 3, n. 1695; C. A. Alex. 30 mai 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 
 461.) 
 
 Effects of novation. 
 
 These are dealt with in the articles C. C. E. 188—191/252, 255. 
 (Cf. C. C. F 1278—1281; C. C. Q. 1176—1180.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: — 
 
 The new debt is not guaranteed by the securities which 
 guaranteed the discharge of the original debt, unless that is the 
 intention of the parties as resulting from the agreement or the 
 circumstances of the case. 
 
 Nevertheless the scope of the agreement shall be limited as 
 follows : — 
 
 hi the first case above mentioned, the debtor and the creditor, 
 may agree that real securities, such as privileges, hijpothecs and 
 right Is of retention, shall be transferred to the new obligation, 
 provided that the burden of such obligation is not increased to 
 the prejudice of third persons. 
 
 In the second case, the creditor and the third person may agree, 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 489 
 
 even without the consent of the original debtor, that the real 
 securities shall be continued. 
 
 In the third case, the three contracting parties may make the 
 like agreement. 
 
 In each of the above cases, personal securities, such as surety- 
 ship or joint and several liability, shall be transferred only with 
 the consent of the sureties or the co-debtors. 
 
 The agreement which transfers such securities can have no effect 
 as regards third persons, unless it is made at the same time m the 
 novation and by means of an official instrument. 
 
 These articles must be considered. 
 
 Transfer of securities to new debt. 
 
 The privileges and hypothecs which attach to an old debt do 
 not pass to the one which is substituted for it unless the creditor 
 has expressly reserved them. Seeing that novation extinguishes 
 the old debt, just as payment would extinguish it, it would at the 
 same time put an end to all the accessory obligations such as 
 suretyship or hypothecs, unless means were taken to preserve them. 
 The law distinguishes between real and personal securities. Per- 
 sonal securities such as suretyships can never be transferred in the 
 literal sense of the term. The sureties may consent to guarantee 
 the new debt, but, if so, they make new obligations. They 
 guaranteed the old one in view of the character and circumstances 
 of the debtor. And it is for them to say if they are willing to 
 guarantee the new debt. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1742; Aubry et 
 Rau, oth ed. 4, p. 370.) 
 
 The transfer of the real securities to the new debt must be made 
 at the same time as the novation, for otherwise the securities will 
 have been extinguished and they cannot subsequently be revived. 
 Of course the creditor may expressly stipulate that the novation 
 shall be conditional on the sureties or others liable in the old debt 
 consenting to make themselves liable under the new one. 
 
 If the new debt is larger than the old one the transfer of the 
 securities to the new debt by the novation is not allowed to injure 
 third parties. The code says: provided that the burden of such 
 obligation is not increased to the prejudice of third persons. 
 (C. C. E. 189/253.) If, for example, I owe you L. E. 10.000, 
 which is secured by hypothec, and we agree to increase the debt to 
 L. E. 15,000, the hypothec to remain, this cannot be allowed to 
 prejudice the holder of a hypothec postponed to the one in your 
 
490 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 favour and registered before the novation. (Pothier, Oblig. 
 n. 599; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1740; Aubrj et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 368, note 53.) 
 
 No transfer of securities to property of new debtor. 
 
 By C. C. F. 1279, when novation is effected by the substitu- 
 tion of a new debtor the original privileges and hypothecs cannot 
 be transferred to the property of the new debtor. 
 
 Obviously, the hypothec upon an immoveable of the old debtor 
 cannot be transferred to another immoveable; hypothecs cannot 
 be transferred from one immoveable to another. If an immove- 
 able of the new debtor is to be made liable, that can only be by 
 a new hypothec. If the new debtor consents to this, the hypothec 
 can of course only take effect from its date and registration, and 
 cannot prejudice his creditors who had privileges and hypothecs 
 over this property before. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1741; Aub'ry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 368, note 54.) 
 
 Is the old debtor's consent necessary to transfer securities? 
 
 The Egyptian Code does not require this in novation by change 
 of the debtor. (C. C. E. 187/251.) Why should the old debtor's 
 consent be required seeing that the novation cannot prejudice him 
 or make him liable to pay any larger amount than before? The 
 law stated by Pothier was otherwise, but the reason given is not 
 very convincing. (Oblig. n. 599; B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 3, 
 n. 1378.) 
 
 In all cases except expromission the debtor takes part in the 
 transaction, and if" it is his immoveable which is hypothecated it 
 would seem that his consent to the novation is a tacit consent to 
 the ''reserve." C. C. E. 189, jal. 2/253, appears to lay down 
 the same rule for expromission. 
 
 In France the point is controversial, but this is largely because 
 if C. C. F. 1278 is to be read as not requiring the debtor's consent, 
 this article would be inconsistent with C. C. F. 1280, which says: 
 Lorsque la novation s'opere entre le creancier et Vun des debiteurs 
 solidaires, les privileges el hijpotheques de Vanciemie creance ne 
 peuvent etre reserves que sur les biens de celui qui contracte la 
 nouveUe dette. But as C. C. F. 1280 is not reproduced in the 
 Egyptian Code we are not confronted with this difficulty. (See 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1738; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 368, note 54.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 491 
 
 Protection of third parties. 
 
 The agreement which transfers such securities can have no effect 
 as regards third persons unless it is made at the same time as 
 the novation and by means of an official instrument. (C. C. E. 
 191/255.) 
 
 The novation extinguishes the securities unless they are reserved 
 or transferred. And how are third parties to know that they are 
 reserved or transferred except by the register? In the absence of 
 the registration they may acquire rights over the immoveables 
 after the novation, and it would be unjust to allow these rights to 
 be affected by a novation of which they were unaware. 
 
 Does the code intend to distinguish as to this point between the 
 case when the real security is " reserved," or, as the Egyptian 
 Code calls it, " continued," and the case when the real security is 
 " transferred," a case which, as we have seen earlier, involves the 
 constitution of a new real security. 
 
 The danger is less serious in the case of a reserve of a hypothec, 
 because the hypothec, being registered, it remains on the register 
 and third parties are protected. 
 
 If D's debt to C is guaranteed by a hypothec over his immove- 
 able, and X agrees to become debtor in D's place, it may be agreed 
 that the debt shall be secured as before by the hypothec over D's 
 immoveable. D is then a real security. In this case we may say 
 the hypothec is reserved or continued. But suppose, instead of 
 this agreement, it is agreed that the hypothec over D's immove- 
 able shall be extinguished, and in place of it X shall grant .a 
 hypothec over an immoveable which belongs to him. There is 
 here a new hypothec. According to the French law it is only in 
 this case that an acte. authentique is needed. (Demolombe, 28 r 
 n. 354; D. Supp. Oblig. n. 1053; Marcade, on art. 1279, n. 3.) 
 
 It is possible that the Egyptian Code intends to preserve this 
 distinction, but the language of the code is far from clear. 
 (C. C. E. 191/255.) More probably the word* " transfer " in 
 this article is used to include " reserves " as well as transfers in the 
 strict sense. (See De Hults, Rep. vo. Novation, n. 23; Halton, 1, 
 386.) 
 
 Novation in case of joint and several debt or debt 
 secured by a surety. 
 
 The French Code has two articles upon novation as effecting a 
 joint and several debt, or a debt secured by a surety. 
 
492 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 When novation is effected between the creditor and one of 
 the joint and several debtors, the privileges and hypothecs which 
 attach to the old debt can be reserved only upon the property of 
 the co-debtor u>ho contracts the new debt. 
 
 Joint and several debtors are discharged by novation effected 
 betweeen the creditor and one of the co-debtors. 
 
 Novation effected with respect to the principal debtor discharges 
 his sureties. 
 
 Nevertheless, if the creditor have stipulated in the first case 
 for the accession of the co-debtors or in the second case lor that of 
 the sureties, the old debt subsists if the co-debtors or the sureties 
 refuse to accede to the new contract. (C. C. F. 1280, 1281; 
 C. C. Q. 1178,1179.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code intends to maintain the same rules, though 
 it states them less fully. (C. C. E. 190/254; De Hults, Rep. 
 Novation, n. 21.) 
 
 One of the joint and several debtors cannot create a hypothec 
 over the property of his co-debtors without their consent, and 
 this is what it would amount to if he could reserve a hypothec 
 over their property. If the creditor agrees to novation with one 
 of the joint and several debtors, he discharges the other joint and - 
 several debtors from their personal liability, and he discharges 
 their lands from hypothecs, if any there be, unless he takes steps 
 to prevent this result. This he can easily do by making his 
 consent to the novation conditional on the other joint and several 
 debtors giving their adhesion to the contract. The same rule 
 applies to the case of novation effected with respect to a principal 
 debtor, whose sureties will be thereby discharged unless precau- 
 tions are taken. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 599; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 369; B.-L. et Barde, 2, n. 1739, and n. 1742.) 
 
 Delegation. 
 
 It is now necessary to examine in more detail the special caae 
 of delegation. 
 
 Pothier defined delegation as a kind of novation by which the 
 old debtor, in order to discharge his debt to his creditor, procures 
 a third person who binds himself to the creditor in his plaqe. 
 {Oblig. n. 600.) It is dealt with in C. C. E. 187, al. 2, 251, al.' 
 2. Il requires, therefore, the concurrence of three persons, the old 
 debtor who finds the substitute and is called in the French law 
 the delcgant, the person substituted or delegated, called the 
 delegue, and the creditor who, in consequence of the new debt 
 
 
 Lv>^m U 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 49& 
 
 which the delegue contracts with him, discharges the debtor who 
 makes the delegation. The creditor is known as the delegated™. 
 There can be no question of novation if it does not appear that 
 the delegue undertook to be substituted in place of the old debtor. 
 (C. A. Alex. 30 nov. 1911, B. L. J. XXIV, 25.) And it is 
 equally essential that the delegataire should have consented to 
 accept the delegue. (C. A. Alex. 26 juin 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 
 418.) Delegation is a contract formed like other contracts by an 
 offer and an acceptance. When the delegataire accepts the offer 
 he acquires a direct right of action against the delegue. (C. A. 
 Alex. 13 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 232.) Delegation of this 
 kind, which is the only one noticed by Pothier, is now called 
 "perfect delegation," and is distinguished from another form 
 called " imperfect delegation," in which, though a new debtor is 
 found, the old debtor is not discharged. According to the French 
 Code, the presumption is in favour of this imperfect delegation, 
 for the French Code says: — 
 
 The delegation by which a debtor gives his creditor a new 
 debtor who obliges himself towards the creditor, does not effect 
 novation unless the creditor Ms expressly declared that he intended 
 to discharge his debtor* who has made the delegation. (C. C. F. 
 1275; Toulouse, 4 avr. 1895, D. 98. 2. 337.) The same pre- 
 sumption exists in Egyptian law. (C. A. Alex. 30 nov. 1911, 
 B. L. J. XXIV, 25; C. A. Alex. 22 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 
 167.) The distinction between perfect and imperfect delegation 
 must be explained. 
 
 Meaning of express discharge. 
 
 In saying that the delegation does not discharge the former 
 debtor without an express declaration to that effect, the French 
 Code does not mean that the word "discharge" must be used. 
 But language must be employed which clearly indicates the inten- 
 tion of the creditor to discharge this debtor. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, 
 n. 1744; Aubry et Bau, 5th ed. 4, p. 363; Paris. 14 dec. 1889, 
 D. 90. 2. 189.) 
 
 Delegation distinguished from novation. 
 
 Delegation does not necessarily involve novation. It is only 
 that variety of delegation which is called perfect delegation in 
 which there must be novation. 
 
 Delegation is a special contract analogous to mandate. Its 
 
494 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 -object is the thing which is stipulated from the person delegated. 
 If the delegator was a debtor and his creditor releases him from 
 the debt and accepts the person delegated in his place, there is 
 novation. There can quite well be delegation without any nova- 
 tion. For example: 
 
 (1) A desires to promise a gift to B. Having no funds avail- 
 able he asks C to promise the gift, and C does so. There is no 
 novation here A will be bound to reimburse C on the principles 
 of mandate. (B.-L- et Barde, 3, n. 1754.) 
 
 (2) In what is called imperfect delegation there is no novation. 
 
 Distinction between perfect delegation and imperfect 
 delegation. 
 
 Delegation is said to be perfect when the creditor declares his 
 intention to liberate the first debtor when he accepts the new one. 
 He has no longer any action against the original debtor. The 
 perfect delegation produces the effect of a novation. (B.-L. et 
 Barde, 3, n. 1744; Aubry et Bau, 5th ed. 4, p. 363; Colin et 
 Capitant, 2, p. 108. See C. A. Alex. 23 dec. 1915, B. L. J. 
 XXVIII, 72; C. A. Alex. 26 janv. 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 418.) 
 
 But, on the other hand, when the creditor has not declared his 
 intention to discharge the original debtor there is no novation. 
 The old debt is not extinguished; there is what is called imperfect 
 delegation, by which is meant that the creditor accepts the obliga- 
 tion of the new debtor without abandoning his claim against the 
 old one: (C. A. Alex. 22 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 167; 
 C. A. Alex. 17 avril 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 320.) The creditor 
 is in much the same position as if he had accepted a surety for 
 the debt due to him. The two kinds of delegation are clearly 
 distinguished in the Mohammedan law. (Kadri Pacha, Statut 
 Reel, arts. 890—891.) 
 
 The distinction between perfect delegation and imperfect dele- 
 gation is important if the new debtor turns out to be insolvent. 
 If in this case the delegation was perfect, the creditor has no 
 recourse against the old debtor. Imperfect delegation is there- 
 fore preferable from the point of view of the creditor, and it is 
 in fact much more common than perfect delegation. (Planiol, 2, 
 n. 554; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 109.) 
 
 Even when the delegation was perfect, and the delegate was 
 insolvent or bankrupt already at the date of the delegation, the 
 French Code allows the creditor a recourse. For it is reasonable 
 to presume that in this case there must have been fraud or error. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 495 
 
 Who would voluntarily accept a bankrupt debtor? (C. C. F. 1276.) 
 The Egyptian law is probably the same. 
 
 Indication of person to pay or to receive payment. 
 
 C. C. F. 1277 states two other cases in which there is no 
 novation, though they resemble cases of delegation: The simple 
 indication by the debtor of a person who is. to spay, in his plaoe, 
 or the simple indication by the creditor of a person ivho is to 
 receive in his place, does not effect novation. And the Quebec 
 Code adds a third case: " or the transfer of a debt, with or without 
 the acceptance of the debtor." (C. C. Q. 1174.) The presump- 
 tion is that the person named by the debtor to make the payment 
 is his agent who is to make the payment on his account. The 
 mandate to make the payment can be revoked, and the creditor 
 is certainly not presumed to accept the agent as his debtor and 
 to discharge the principal. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, 
 nos. 1745, 1754.) 
 
 In like manner when the creditor names a person to receive 
 payment for him, the presumption is that this is merely as the* 
 creditor's agent. (See C. A. Alex. 13 mars 1913, B. L. J. 
 XXV, 232.) 
 
 Distinction between novation by change of creditor and 
 assignment of a claim. 
 
 There is considerable resemblance between novation by 
 change of the creditor and the assignment of a claim. But the 
 two things need to be carefully distinguished. The fundamental 
 differences are: — 
 
 (1) That novation extinguishes the old debt with its acces- 
 sories, unless it is agreed that the securities shall pass to the new 
 debt, whereas, in the assignment of a claim, the claim is trans- 
 ferred with its accessories to the new creditor. 
 
 In novation the new debt is not guaranteed by the securities 
 which guaranteed the discharge of the original debt, unless that 
 is the intention of the parties as resulting from the agreement 
 or the circumstances of the case. 
 
 (2) There is another difference, namely, that novation by 
 change of the creditor requires the consent of the debtor, whereas 
 an assignment of the debt can be made by the French law and, in 
 Egypt, by the Mixed Code, without his consent. (B.-L. et Barde, 
 3, n. 1722; Demolombe, 28, nos. 272, 330; Colin et Capitant, 2, 
 
496 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 p. '102; Cass. 23 nov. 1898, D. 99. 1. 21; C. C. M. 251, 
 436; C. A. Alex. 20 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXIV, 203.) Bat 
 under the Native Civil Code this difference between novation and 
 assignment does not exist, because that code, following upon this 
 point the Mohammedan law, requires the consent of the debtor 
 in the case of assignment also. But this is without prejudice to 
 the rules of commerce in regard to the assignment of commercial 
 documents of title and instruments transferable by endorsement. 
 (C. C. N. 349; Grandmoulin, Contrats, n. 240; Halton, 2, p. 87.) 
 
 (4) Release. 
 
 This is the fourth mode of extinction. 
 
 In regard to release, or, as it is called in the French law, remise 
 de la dctte, the modern civil law is much simpler than the Roman 
 law on which it was based. In the Roman law there were many 
 technicalities as to the form of release, but in our law all these 
 subtleties have disappeared, and no special forms are required for 
 release. (See Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 712; Pothier, Oblig. 
 n. 607.) By release is meant the gratuitous renunciation made 
 by a creditor in favour of his debtor of the right to claim the 
 whole or a part of the debt. There is no payment, or giving in 
 payment, or substitution of a new debtor, there is simply an 
 abandonment of the debt. 
 
 It is true that in novation or compromise there is frequently the 
 release of a debt as a part of the operation. 
 
 But release, in the sense here intended, means a gratuitous' 
 abandonment by the creditor of his right, and is, in fact, as Pothier 
 calls it, a gift. {Oblig. to. 619.) 
 
 Consequently, the release requires acceptance either express or 
 
 J&ciL (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1767; Laurent, 18, n. 337; Aubry 
 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 335. See, however, Larombiere, art. 1285, 
 
 n. 10. Cf. C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 118, 
 
 Mohammedan law.) 
 
 It is perhaps singular that although release is in truth a dona- 
 tion, it is not subject to the conditions as to the formalities of 
 gifts. But the true character of release as a gift is shown by the 
 fact that although the forms of gifts are not required for its 
 validity, it is subject to the rules which apply to gifts as regards 
 the capacity to give and receive. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 
 Oblig. 3, 1769; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 336; Colin et 
 Capitant, 2, p. 124.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 497 
 
 The articles on release in the Egyptian Code are as follows 
 (C. C. E. 180—185/243—248;:- 
 
 Au obligation is extinguished by a voluntary release made 
 by the creditor, provided he has capacity to make a gift. 
 
 A release granted to the debtor discharges his sureties. 
 
 A release granted to one of several debtors jointly and severally 
 liable is deemed to have been granted for his share and extin- 
 guishes the liability as regards such share only. 
 
 The rest of the debtors so jointly and severally liable can re- 
 cover against the one to whom the release has been granted only 
 his contribution to the share of those of them, if any, who are 
 insolvent. 
 
 A release granted to a surety is deemed to be granted in respect 
 of his suretyship. 
 
 If the undertaking of suretyship entered into by the surety to 
 whom the release has been granted is not subsequent to that of 
 other sureties for the same obligation, he remains liable to the 
 recourse, if any, of such other sureties against him. 
 
 Most of these articles need no commentary here. The question 
 as to release in the case of the joint and several debt has been 
 fully discussed under that head. (Supra, pp. 422 seq.) 
 
 The articles upon release in the case of suretyship belong to 
 the contract of suretyship. (See Halton, 2, p. 222; Grandmoulin, 
 Suretes, n. 81.) 
 
 Release may be tacit. 
 
 So true is it that by our law no special form is required for 
 the release of a debt that it may be inferred from the conduct of 
 the parties. 
 
 In the Egyptian Code these rules are given in the chapter on 
 proof of obligations. The delivery to the debtor of the original 
 document of title or of a copy endorsed for execution is proof of 
 discharge. It is, nevertheless, open to the creditor to prove by 
 witnesses that the document of title is in the hands of the debtor 
 for some entirely different reason. (C. C. E. 219, 220/284, 285.) 
 
 The release of an obligation may be made either expressly or 
 tacitly by persons legally capable of alienating. It is made tacitly 
 when the creditor voluntarily surrenders to his debtor the original 
 title of the obligation unless there is proof of a contrary intention . 
 So if the creditor holds a promissory note for the debt and he 
 gives it back to the debtor without payment there is a presumption 
 that he intends to release the debtor. But this is merely a pre- 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 32 
 
498 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 sumption which may be rebutted by proof of a contrary intention. 
 It may be proved that the note or other title to the debt had been 
 given to the debtor to copy, or for some other purpose, or had been 
 sent to him by mistake, or that he had got possession of it fraudu- 
 lently. It is only the voluntary surrender by the creditor of the 
 title which raises a presumption of intention to release the debt. 
 By the French Code, if the original title to the debt is a private 
 writing, and it is proved to have been voluntarily handed to the 
 debtor, it is not competent to prove that this was for any other 
 purpose than to extinguish the debt. (C. C. F. 1282.) If the 
 document is found in the debtor's hands he does not need to prove 
 that it came into his hands by the voluntary act of the creditor, 
 for the presumption will be that this was so. It is quite excep- 
 tional that a man should get possession of a document by error 
 or theft, or in any other way than by its being voluntarily given 
 to him. (Planiol, 2, n. 615; Baudry-Laeant. et Barde, Oblig. 
 3, n. 1781; Cass. 20 oct. 1890, D. 91. 1. 263.) 
 
 But the creditor may prove by any means of proof that delivery 
 to the debtor was not voluntary in this sense. For instance, when 
 it is proved that the debtor had been the tutor of the creditor, and 
 had after the termination of the tutorship continued to manage 
 the business of the creditor, the fact that he is in possess! ion of 
 the document of debt is easily explained. (Aubry et Rau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 340; Req. 6 aout 1894, D. 95. 1. 165.) On the other 
 hand, by the French law, if the original title is a notarial deed, 
 the voluntary handing of the grosse or copy of the title raises a 
 presumption of release, but a presumption which may be rebutted. 
 (C. C. F. 1283; Cass. 7 janv. 1907, D. 1907. 1. 40.) In our 
 law this distinction is not made. 
 
 By C. C. F. 1286: The surrender of a thing given in pledge 
 does not create a presumption of the release of the debt for which 
 it ivas pledged. The pledge being merely a security, and acces- 
 sory to the principal obligation, it is quite possible that the 
 creditor gave back the pledge because he was satisfied with the 
 personal security of the debtor. The Egyptian law is the same. 
 The code says, a pledge is cancelled if the thing pledged returns 
 into the possession of the pledgor. (C. C. E. 541/663.) But 
 this does not affect the debt secured. By C. C. F. 1284; C. C. Q. 
 1183, the surrender of the original title of an obligation to one 
 of joint and several debtors is available in favour of his co-debtors. 
 Two reasons may be given for this: 
 
 (1) That each of the joint and several debtors is the agent 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 499 
 
 of them all for the purpose of ameliorating their condition, 
 and 
 
 (2) That by giving up the title of the debt to one of them, the 
 creditor disarms himself as against the others, because he would 
 need the title if he were to sue them. This second reason is so 
 •conclusive that, probably, the presumption of release would exist 
 also where the debtors were not joint and several but merely 
 joint. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Obiig. 3, n. 1800; Aubry et 
 Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 340.) 
 
 The Egyptian law is no doubt the same. 
 
 The tacit release goes further here than express release, because 
 by the Egyptian law, express release is presumed to be only of 
 the debtor's share. (C. C. E. 183/246.) 
 
 This subject has been discussed fully under the head of joint 
 .and several obligations. (Supra, pp. 422 seq.) 
 
 (5) Compensation. 
 
 Compensation is the fifth of the modes in which an obligation 
 may be extinguished. 
 
 Compensation is the balance struck between two debts which 
 cancel each other either in whole or in part. It takes place when 
 I owe you a sum of money and you owe me another sum. If I 
 borrow L. E. 100 from you on Thursday, and on Saturday you 
 buy from me goods for cash worth L. E. 100, then I no longer 
 owe you the L. E. 100 for the loan. It has been wiped out by 
 the debt which you owe me for the goods which you bought and 
 did not pay for. 
 
 Where the one debt cancels the other in this way automatically 
 this is what is called legal compensation, and it is this form of 
 compensation which is treated of in the Civil Code: 
 
 Compensation is a mode of payment which takes place, by 
 effect of law, even without the knowledge of the parties, when 
 each, is both debtor and creditor of the other. 
 
 Compensation operates up to the \amount of the smaller debt. 
 (C. C. E. 192, 193/256, 257.) The French Code is to the same 
 effect. (C. C. F. 1289, 1290 
 
 But, on careful examination, it will be found that there are in 
 fact three varieties of compensation which are called by French 
 writers legal, facultative, and judicial or reconventional. The 
 first is that which takes place ipso jure, as in the illustration just 
 mentioned; the second is that which occurs when there is some- 
 
 32 (2) 
 
500 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 thing to prevent legal compensation, but the obstacle is created 
 by law solely in the interest of one party and ho chooses to waivei 
 it, thus allowing the legal compensation to take place; and the 
 third is that which takes place when in a litigation the judge 
 compensates one claim with another, the claims not being of such 
 a nature as to compensate each other without any judicial investi- 
 gation and decision. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1807; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 371.) Judicial compensation which occurs when 
 tin' validity of a demande reconventionnelle is sustained belongs 
 to the subject of procedure. (See C. C. Proc. E. 294/335; Lusena 
 Bey, Elements de Procedure Civile et Commerciale, 1, p. 346; 
 C. A. Alex. 9 fevr. 1899, B. L. J. XI, 125.) We need to speak 
 only of legal and of facultative compensation. 
 
 (a) Legal compensation. 
 
 This comes into operation only where both obligations are 
 for a liquidated amount, are due, and have for their object a sum 
 of money or any other things of the like nature which, having 
 regard to their kind and value, can be replaced by each other, and 
 which are payable or deliverable in the same place. (C. C. E. 
 194/258: C. C. F. 1291.) These conditions will be more fully 
 explained later. 
 
 When the conditions stated exist, and the two debts are of 
 equal amount, they are both extinguished without any agreement 
 of parties or the judgment of a court. If I owe you L. E. 100. 
 of which the payment is due, and, subsequently, you come to owe 
 me L. E. 100, which is likewise payable, the two debts cancel 
 each other and disappear. If we prefer to put it another way the 
 one debt pays the other, for, as French lawyers say, compenser 
 cest payer. And if, in the circumstances stated, my debt to you 
 is of L. E. 100, and your debt to me is of L. E. 50. then my 
 debt becomes automatically one of L. E. 50. Seeing that it is 
 the law which declares that this effect shall be produced, the 
 knowledge of the parties is not necessary, nor is it necessary that 
 they should have capacity to contract. (Laurent, 18, n. 382; 
 Planiol, 2, n. 579.) 
 
 Can court declare compensation ex officio? 
 
 In the French law there is a controversy as to whether the court 
 has the duty of declaring ex officio that compensation has taken 
 place. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 501 
 
 According to some authorities, the compensation is not allowed 
 if the defendant has not taken the plea. (Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 396.) 
 
 A recent decision of the Mixed Court of Appeal is in this sense. 
 (C. A. Alex. 12 janv. 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 109.) Obviously, 
 the court cannot divine for itself that there is compensation. But 
 when it is seized of demands by both parties, the better opinion 
 seems to be that the court may find that compensation has taken 
 place though the plea is not formally taken. (Demolombe, 28, 
 n. 643; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1861; Larombiere, art. 1290, 
 n. 1; D. N. C. C. art. 1290, n. 2.) 
 
 Compensation first pleaded in appeal. 
 
 Compensation may be pleaded at any stage of the proceedings, 
 and even on appeal, though the plea was not taken in the court 
 below. (Demolombe, 28, n. 645; Aubry et Rau, 5th eel. 4, 
 p. 396.) But it is only if the debt is truly liquid that it may 
 be for the first time pleaded in compensation upon appeal, the 
 plea not having been taken in the court below. S'il est vrai 
 qiien principe la compensation est un moyen de liberation qui, 
 comme le paiement, p&ut etre propose pour la premiere fois en 
 degre d'appel, il n'est pas moins vrai que, lorsque la compensation 
 implique au prealable la decision d'ime question qui pent, a elle 
 seule, former Vobjet d'une action separee, il nest pas permis a 
 une des parties de gctrder le silence en premier degre, et d'attendre 
 pour la proposer que la cause soit portee devant la Cour, privant 
 ainsi Vadversaire d'une des plus importantes garanties judiciaires. 
 (C. A. Alex. 16 janv. 1916, B. L. J. XXIX, 151. See Cass. 
 5 nov. 1901, D. 1902. 1. 92.) 
 
 What debts can be compensated. 
 
 This legal compensation takes place only in regard to certain 
 debts, and it is these which must now be examined. 
 
 (1) The debts must be reciprocal. 
 
 By this is meant that each of the parties must be creditor in 
 one of two obligations, and debtor in the other in his personal 
 character and as a principal. (See C. A. Alex. 4 fevr. 1903, 
 B. L. J. XV, 132; C. A. Alex. 25 nov. 1915, B. L. J. XXVIII, 
 35; Cass. 5 nov. 1901, D. 1902. 1. 92; Cass. 7 fevr. 1905, 
 D. 1905. 1. 432.) 
 
502 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 If a tutor brings an action in his quality, it cannot be pleaded 
 that the debt is compensated by onie which the tutor owes as an 
 individual. If an heir who has accepted a succession subject to 
 benefit of inventory, sues a creditor of the succession for a debt due 
 to him as an individual, it cannot be pleaded that the debt was 
 compensated by a debt due by the succession to the defendant. 
 (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1810.) Similarly a debtor 
 cannot set up compensation between the debt which he owes and 
 a debt due by the creditor to a third party on whose behalf the 
 debtor is entitled to act as agent. (C. A. Alex. 25 nov. 1915 y 
 
 B. L. J. XXVIII, 35.) 
 
 And, seeing that a partnership has a persona distinct from 
 those of the individual partners, a debt due to the firm cannot be 
 compensated with a debt due by a partner or vice versa. (Cass. 
 5 nov. 1901, D. 1902. 1. 92; Pand. Franc. Oblig. 5845.) So 
 it has been held, Le creancier personnel d'un associe, meme en 
 nom collectif, ne saw ait opposer une compensation a la societe. 
 (C. A. Alex. 20 avril 1910, B. L. J. XXII, 275.) 
 
 This principle that reciprocity between the two debts is neces- 
 sary is illustrated in the law of suretyship. 
 
 The surety may email himself of the compensation which takes 
 place when the creditor owes the principal debtor. (C. C. F. 
 1294; C. C. E. 509/622; Grandmoulin, Suretes, n. 80. See 
 
 C. C. E. 198/262.) 
 
 But a principal debtor cannot set up in compensation that 
 which is due to his surety. (C. C. E. 200/264.) 
 
 A. co-debtor jointly and severally liable with others cannot 
 set up in compensation that which is due to his co-debtors' ex- 
 cepting to the extent of the share of the latter in the liability. 
 (C. C. E. 201/265; C. C. F. 1294.) 
 
 Here the first case is perfectly obvious. If the creditor incurs 
 a debt to the principal debtor, the debt due by the principal debtor 
 is to that extent wiped out. It would not be equitable that 
 thereafter the creditor should continue to have a claim against 
 the surety. The surety can say, "you have been paid by the 
 principal debtor whose debt I guaranteed." The second case is 
 a good illustration of the point under discussion. If the creditor 
 incurs a debt to the surety, the principal debtor cannot say that 
 his debt to the creditor has been thereby discharged. The debt 
 which the surety owed to the creditor he did not owe as principal 
 but as surety. His debt was conditional on the failure of the 
 principal debtor to pay, and if compensation were allowed the 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 503 
 
 effect of this would be to make the surety pay before his time 
 had come, that is before the principal debtor had been tried aud 
 found wanting. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1813; Demolombe, 28, 
 n. 550.) 
 
 The third case is that in which there are joint and several 
 debtors. Here, if the creditor incurs a debt to one of the joint 
 and several debtors, this does extinguish the debt to the extent 
 of the share of the joint and several debtor, and this compensation 
 can be pleaded by the other co-debtors. 
 
 For the. joint and several debtors are, in a question with the 
 creditor, all of them in the position of principal debtors. 
 
 This case is not mentioned in the French article, and in the 
 French law no compensation takes place even to the extent of 
 the share of the co-debtor. (C. C. F. 1294; Baudry-Lacant. et 
 Barde, Oblig. 2, nos. 1249, 1250. See supra, p. 420.) 
 
 (2) The debts which are compensated must be of the same 
 kind, or be fungible. 
 
 The French writers express this by saying that the two debts 
 must possess the character of fungibility. They must be both 
 debts of money, or else both debts of a certain quantity of fungi- 
 bles of the same kind. There can be no compensation between 
 determinate specific things. One cannot set off a debt of a horse 
 against a debt of another horse, or even a debt of a certain quantity 
 of wheat of one quality against a debt of a certain quantity of 
 wheat of a different quality, for these things are not fungible 
 inter se. (See Req. 22 nov. 1899, D. 1900. 1. 14.) If com- 
 pensation were to be allowed in such cases it would be compelling 
 a creditor to receive in payment something different from that 
 which he had stipulated for, and, according to the law, a creditor 
 cannot be compelled to receive any other thing than the one due 
 to him, although the thing offered be of greater value than the 
 thing due. (C. C. F. 1243; C. C. E. 168/231. Supra, p. 451.) 
 
 Under the French Code there is an exception of a limited kind. 
 
 Where a debtor has promised to make payments or prestations 
 of a certain quantity of grain or other produce which has a fixed 
 market price officially determined on a certain date, such a debt 
 may be compensated with money. But our law has nothing of 
 this kind, and it is criticised by the French writers. (C. C. F, 
 1291; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1828; Pothier, 
 Oblig. n. 626.) 
 
504 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 (3) The two debts must both be demandable. 
 
 The third requirement for compensation is that the two debts 
 shall both be demandable, which means: (1) that both the debts 
 shall be exigible in their character; and (2) that each of them is 
 a debt which the creditor has the right to sue for at once. As 
 to (1) the English version of the Egyptian codes is not very 
 clear. In saying that the obligations must be "due," the code 
 might mean merely that the date of payment must have arrived. 
 But the French version says the debts must be exigibles. This 
 is the word used in the corresponding article of the French Code. 
 It clearly implies that the debt must be one the payment of which 
 could be demanded by the creditor.. A natural obligation, for 
 example, does not entitle the creditor to demand performance. 
 It is not an exigible debt, though it may be "due," in the sense 
 that the date fixed for payment has arrived. The French doctrine 
 is in this sense. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1839; Aubry et Bau, 5th 
 ed. 4, p. 377; Demolombe, 28, n. 536, 543.) The Egyptian 
 law is without doubt the same. (De Hults, Rep. vo. Compensa- 
 tion, n. 11.) ► 
 
 As to (2), if one of the debts is not due for three months, and 
 the other is actually due, compensation cannot take place between 
 them, because this would be depriving the debtor of the benefit of 
 the term or delay to which lie is entitled by the agreement or 
 by law. But the creditor in whose favour the term exists can, if 
 he chooses, waive the benefit of the term, and this will allow 
 compensation to take place. 
 
 For example, if I owe ypu L. E. 500 payable in three months 
 without interest, and you incur a debt to me of the same amount, 
 which is exigible now, I can insist that compensation shall take 
 place between the two debts, if I choose to waive the delay. This 
 is what is called facultative compensation and will be explained 
 later. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1883; Cass. 25 nov. 1891, D. 92. 
 1. 296.) 
 
 It does not apply where the term is in favour of both parties, 
 in which case it cannot be waived without their joint consent. 
 The term of a bill of exchange, for example, is of this kind'. 
 {Vernier v. Kent, 1902, R. J. Q. 11 K. B. 373.) 
 
 (4) The debts must be liquidated. 
 
 The fourth condition of compensation is that the debts shall 
 be liquidated — claires et liquides — and it is with regard to this 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 505 
 
 matter that most of the difficulty arises. According to the old 
 definition, a debt is liquid when it is certain that it is due and 
 what is its amount — cum cerium est an et quantum debeatur. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 628.) 
 
 Debt uncertain. 
 
 Obviously one cannot set up in compensation a claim of which 
 the very existence is disputed. This would be in effect to make 
 the other pay at once a debt which he perhaps did not owe at all. 
 (Pothier, Oblig. n. 628; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 374; C. A. 
 Alex. 10 dec. 1914, B. L. J. XXVII, 59; C. A. ALex. 16 mai 
 1918, B. L. J. XXX, 435; C. A. Alex. 20 mars 1913, B. L. J. 
 XXV, 250.) The creditor of a liquid debt against whom 
 there is set up in compensation a debt which, according to him, 
 is subject to rescission, must bring the action for rescission. The 
 plea has the effect of a mise en demeure. (Demolombe, 28, n. 545 ; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 380. See C. A. Alex. 10 dec. 1914, 
 B. L. J. XXVII, 59.) 
 
 Debt not liquid. 
 
 When the amount of the debt is disputed, and it cannot be 
 ascertained without serious investigation, the debt is not liquid. 
 (Cass. 7 fevr. 1905, D. 1905. 1. 432; C. A. Alex. 11 juin 1914, 
 
 B. L. J. XXVI, 425; C. A. Alex. 17 mai 1916, B. L. J. 
 XXVIII, 338; C. A. Alex. 20 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 381; 
 
 C. A. Alex. 4 mai 1904, B. L. J. XVI, 233; C. A. Alex. 12 
 fevr. 1908, B. L. J. XX, 84.) So it has been held that com- 
 pensation ne peut avoir lieu lorsque la fixation dn montant de 
 Vune dcs creances depend du resultat d"une expertise, et qu'en 
 supposant quit appartienne au juge d'evaluer provisoirement ce 
 montant, les elements d 'appreciation lid font df.faut. (C. A. 
 Alex. 11 juin 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 425.) 
 
 But the law, at least in France, does not require that for com- 
 pensation the debt should be absolutely determined or liquid. It 
 is enough if it is capable of being liquidated promptly and sum- 
 marily. As Pothier puts it, the party who opposes such a debt in 
 compensation must have la preure a la main. (Oblig. n. 628; 
 B.-L. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1833, 1. See C. A. Alex. 16 janv. 
 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 151.) 
 
 This view is settled in the jurisprudence in France, though it 
 is criticised by some writers as contrary to the text of the code. 
 
506 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Laurent, for example, says: " The 'moment a liquidation is neces- 
 sary, whether it is easy or not, the claim is not liquid. It will be 
 so only after the liquidation; till then legal compensation is in- 
 conceivable. In effect, to compensate is to pay. Now, how is 
 it conceivable that the debtor should pay without knowing the 
 amount of his debt? Legal compensation is impossible. The 
 compensation can only be judicial, that is, it will come into 
 existence only when the judge has decided what is the amount of 
 the claim;' (18, n. 404.) 
 
 But although there is a good deal of force in this criticism, the 
 contrary view is settled in practice in France. 
 
 (5) The debts must be payable in the same place. 
 
 The Egyptian codes add another condition, viz., that the debts 
 shall be both payable or deliverable in the same place. 
 (C. C. E. 194/258.) 
 
 This condition is extremely puzzling, and it looks very like a 
 pure mistake. The rule as regards money-debts is that they are 
 payable at the domicile of the debtor. If Zaki living in London 
 owes L. E. 100 to Ahmed in Cairo, and Ahmed incurs a debt 
 of the same amount to Zaki, what reason is there for npt allowing 
 compensation? 
 
 To apply strictly the words of the article would be to exclude 
 compensation in a great number of cases where upon grounds of 
 equity compensation ought to be allowed. The only possible 
 objection to allowing it is that to pay Ahmed's debt in London 
 instead of at Cairo may put him to some expense or cause him 
 some loss. The French Code has an article in the following terms 
 to provide for this: — 
 
 When the tiro debts are not payable in the same place, com- 
 pensation cannot be set up without allowing for the expenses of 
 the remittance. (C. C. F. 1296; C. C. Q. 1193.) This is 
 entirely reasonable. Ahmed in the illustration given, bargained 
 to bo paid in Cairo. If he is paid in London he will lose the 
 costs of the exchange between London and Cairo, or, in other 
 words, the expense of sending the money from the one place to 
 the other. But that is not sufficient reason for refusing altogether 
 to allow compensation to operate. It is contended by some writers 
 that the Egyptian legislator means only to reproduce the provi- 
 sions of the French Code as to the payment of the costs of remit- 
 tance. (Halton. 1, p. 387; Do Hults, Rep. vo. Compensation, 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 507 
 
 11. 14.; If this be so, it must bo admitted that the Egyptian 
 Code is expressed in a singularly unfortunate way. 
 
 It must be pointed out that this payment of the costs of re- 
 mittance may not always be a complete indemnity. The pari \ 
 who relies on payment in a particular place may have made some 
 arrangement to employ the money there and at once, and this 
 arrangement may be defeated by the payment at another place. 
 The German Code with good reason says that the party who 
 invokes the compensation must make good the damage suffered 
 by the other party (art. 391. See note by M. Saleillos to 
 French Translation). 
 
 Exceptional cases in which legal compensation is not 
 permitted. 
 
 When the conditions above explained are fulfilled, compensa- 
 tion takes place whatever be the cause or consideration of the 
 debts, or of either of them, except in the following cases: — 
 
 (1) The demand in restitution of a thing of which the owner 
 has been unjustly deprived; 
 
 (2) The demand in restitution of a deposit of a sum of money 
 or of a quantity of fungibles; 
 
 (3) A debt which has for its object a thing not liable to seizure.. 
 Two of these exceptions are stated in C. C. E. 195/259. 
 
 Compensation does not operate where ivhat is owed on the 
 one side is not a thing liable to seizure, or is the restitution of a 
 deposit of a sum of money or of things which can be replaced 
 by each other. (Cf. C. C. F. 1293; C. C. Q. 1190; German 
 Code, 393; Swiss Code des Obligations, 125.) 
 
 (1) The first of these exceptions is an application of the old 
 maxim spoliatus ante omnia restituendus. (Pothier, Oblig. 
 n. 625; Req. 24 avril 1903, D. 1904. 1. 115.) It is contra rv 
 to public policy to allow a man who has a claim of any kind to 
 enforce it by his own hands against opposition except in the casi 
 where he is himself recapturing something which has been taken 
 away from him wrongfully and by force. If he seizes the pro- 
 perty of his debtor without judicial authority he is not allowed 
 to keep it, although his claim may be a good one. He must first 
 give back what he has improperly taken, and then, if he chooses, 
 he may make his claim in a legal manner. 
 
 And the same rule applies to cases in which the possession has 
 been obtained by fraud or accident. If the thing of which the 
 
508 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 owner has been unjustly deprived is a specific thing — a corps 
 certain — there could not in any case be compensation, because, as 
 we have seen, compensation is only between debts of money or 
 fungibles. And if a bag of money were stolen and the money 
 left intact in the bag, this would still be a corps certain. The 
 kind of case in which there might be compensation, but for the 
 prohibition in this article, is the case where the spoliator had 
 got possession of a sum of money and had consumed it, or mingled 
 it with his own money so that it could no longer be identified. 
 
 In such a case if he were sued for it he could not plead in 
 compensation that the plaintiff owed him a debt. (Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, -Oblig. 3, n. 1854; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 4, p. 388; Demolombe, 28, nos. 588, 590.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code omits this case, but it can hardly be doubted 
 that the Egyptian law is the same as the French law upon this 
 point. (See, however, De Hults, Rep. vo. Compensation, n. 25.) 
 (2) The second rule, like the first, is a traditional rule of the 
 French law. It is taken from the Roman law. In causa depositi 
 compensation i locus non est, sed res ipsa reddendo, est. (Paul, 
 Sentences, 2, 12. See Girard, Manuel, 5th ed. p. 708.) 
 
 As Pothier says, it would not be necessary to state the rule in 
 the case of a deposit of a corps certain, such as a box of (silver, 
 or a bag of money sealed up and labelled. 
 
 In such a case, there could not be compensation under the 
 French law even without this article, upon the general principle 
 that compensation does not apply to specific things. It could 
 only be in the case of irregular deposit, that is, the form of deposit 
 in which the depositary becomes the owner of the thing deposited 
 subject to the obligation of returning an equivalent amount, that 
 the rule here stated would apply. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 625. See 
 Trib. Civ. de Saint-Omer, 6 dec. 1901, D. 1903. 2. 193, note 2; 
 D. X. C. C. art. 1932, nos. 42 seq.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code is upon this point more accurate than the 
 French Code. The French article speaks of "deposit," generally, 
 though it does not allow compensation between debts of corps 
 certains, whereas the Egyptian article speaks only of a deposit 
 of money or fungibles, that is of " irregular deposit." C. C. E. 
 195 259; C. C. F. 1293.) 
 
 According to some French authorities the rule would apply to 
 a deposit with a bank. The bank would not be entitled to com- 
 pensate a debt due by its customer to the bank with a debt due 
 by the bank to him, if the bank's debt is to restore money 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 509 
 
 deposited by the customer. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 
 3, n. 1856. 
 
 But the prevailing view seems to be against this, and rightly 
 so. A deposit with a bank, although in popular language it bears 
 the name of deposit, is in reality a kind of loan. 
 
 The customer lends his money to the bank in order that the 
 bank should make use of it and make it productive, and should 
 return it to him on demand, or subject to certain conditions as to 
 notice, etc. 
 
 The money deposited becomes for the time being the property 
 of the banker, and the claim of the customer against the banker 
 is not a " demand in restitution," but is a simple claim for so 
 much money. This being the true view of the matter, if the 
 customer owes the banker a debt upon another account, it is 
 obviously equitable that compensation should be allowed between 
 the two debts. (Larombiere, on art. 1293, n. 3; Hue, 8, n. 160; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 1293, n. 32; B.-L. et Wahl, Societe, etc., n. 
 1097, 1102, 1117; Panel. Franc. Oblig. n. 5911.) An opinion in 
 this sense has been pronounced by the Court of King's Bench of 
 Quebec. {Vernier v. Kent, 1902, R. J. Q. 11 K. B. 373.) 
 
 Rule not necessary in case of loan for use. 
 
 The French article adds here to the case of deposit the case of 
 loan for use, and says compensation is not allowed in the case 
 de la demande en restitution dVun depot et du pret a usage. 
 (C. C. F. 1293.) 
 
 Pothier limited the exception to deposit, and the French eodi- 
 fiers were not well guided in adding loan for use. For loan for 
 use is a loan of specific things and not of fungibles, and compen- 
 sation therefore would be excluded in any case. (Larombiere, 
 on art. 1293, n. 4; Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1856.) 
 
 In saying that the depositary called upon to return the deposit 
 cannot claim compensation with a debt due to him by the de- 
 positor, it is not, of course, intended to exclude his right to retain 
 the thing deposited until he has been paid the expenses incurred 
 by him on account of the deposit, or any loss which the deposit 
 may have caused to him. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 625; C. C. E. 
 488/596, 597: C. C. F. 1947, 1948; C. C. Q. 1812.) And as 
 regards such claims as we have seen above, he can plead compensa- 
 tion when the deposit is " irregular deposit." (Pothier, I.e.) 
 
510 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Debt not liable to seizure. 
 
 The third exception that compensation does not operate when 
 one of the debts is not liable to seizure is given in the Egyptian 
 Code in more general terms than in the French Code. The 
 French Code speaks only of alimentary allowances. Certain pro- 
 visions are by law alimentary and exempt from seizure. Such 
 are alimentary allowances granted by the court. If this provision 
 in the hands of the debtor is unseizable, the meaning of this is 
 that it is not liable for his ordinary debts, and the object of the 
 rule would be defeated if a creditor could take payment by way 
 of compensation. (See Cass. 3 juill. 1912, D. 1913. 1. 110.) 
 The Egyptian Code. applies the same principle to a "thing liable 
 to seizure." This is an unhappy expression. If it were a specific 
 thing compensation would be excluded by the preceding article. 
 (C. C. E. 194/258.) The rule that compensation is prohibited 
 when one of the debts is unseizable applies to pensions and other 
 debts declared by law to be not subject to arrestment or so subject 
 only up to a certain amount or upon certain conditions. (See 
 C. C. Pro. 434/496; Lusena, Elements de Procedure Civile, 2, 
 p. 73.) 
 
 Up to the proportion specified by the law and subject to the 
 conditions therein stated compensation is allowed. So, for 
 example, if an Egyptian Government official were in arrears with 
 his land-tax, the Government could not deduct the amount of his 
 tax from his salary. But if the official owed the Government a 
 debt arising out of the exercise of his official duties, they could 
 make a deduction to the extent of one-fourth of his salary. 
 (Decree of Feb. 25, 1890; Gelat, 2, p. 555.) 
 
 Effects of legal compensation. 
 
 When compensation takes place the position is the same as if 
 the two debts had been paid. If the debts are of equal amount 
 they are both entirely extinguished with their accessories, and 
 interest ceases to run upon them. If they are of unequal amount 
 the lesser one is extinguished, and it is only the balance of the 
 greater one which remains due. There is one case in which this 
 would do an injustice, viz., if the debts are not payable at the 
 same place. And we have explained earlier how any injustice 
 that might arise from this case is prevented. If we remember 
 the rule compenser cest payer the consequences which follow from 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 511 
 
 compensation are obvious. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 636; Demolombe, 
 28, n. 649; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1864.) 
 
 Imputation. 
 
 Imputation takes place in the case of compensation in the 
 same way as in the case of ordinary payment. (C. C. E. 
 196 — 260.) This is very simple. We have to suppose a debtor 
 who owes two debts to the same creditor. The creditor then incurs 
 a debt to him. With which of the twq debts does compensation 
 take place? If John owes William two debts of L. E. 500 each, 
 of which one is secured by a hypothec and bears interest, and the 
 other is for rent or for goods sold, and William becomes debtor 
 to John for L. E. 500, this do/bt will be compensated by pre- 
 ference with the L. E. 500 which John owed on the loan secured 
 by the hypothec, because it is more for his interest that this debt 
 should be extinguished than the other. The French law is the 
 same. (C. C. F. 1297; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1864; Req. 3 mai 
 1860, D. 61. 1. 104; supra, p. 469.) The question to ask is 
 which debt would have been extinguished, according to the rules 
 of imputation, if John had paid L. E. 500? 
 
 Compensation not to prejudice third parties. 
 
 This matter is treated of in the Egyptian Code in these terms: 
 
 A debtor who has consented to the assignment of a claim 
 against him, which is subject to compensation, may no longer set 
 up compensation as against the assignees; he can only enforce 
 his original claim against the assignor. 
 
 When a creditor has paid a debt against which he might have 
 set up a claim in compensation, sureties, co-debtors jointly and 
 severally liable, creditors with a privilege or hypothec ranking 
 after the claim, and a third party,, owner of a .thing given in 
 'pledge to secure it, may always set up compensation, unless the 
 creditor had, when paying the debt, goad grounds for being 
 ignorant of the existence of the claim which he could have set up 
 in compensation. (C. C. E. 197, 198/261, 262; C. C. F. 1295, 
 1299; C. C. Q. 1196, 1197.) 
 
 If the debtor who had a right to plead compensation does not 
 avail himself of his right, but pays the debt, the debt is extin- 
 guished and the hypothecs or suretyships by which the debt was 
 guaranteed fall of necessity to the ground. By paying the debt 
 when he might have claimed compensation, the debtor is held 
 
512 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 to have renounced his right to that plea, and to have relied for 
 payment of the debt due to him on the personal security of hie 
 debtor. 
 
 Kamel owes Zaky L. E. 100, and Zaky, likewise, owes Kamel 
 L. E. 100, for which Ahmed is surety. Zaky demands payment 
 from Kamel, and Kamel instead of pleading compensation, pays 
 the debt. Kamel can now claim his debt from Zaky, but he 
 cannot fall back upon Ahmed if Zaky does not pay. Ahmed 
 can say, "you got payment if you had been sensible enough to 
 take it." 
 
 But this rule is subject to an equitable exception. That is 
 when the plea of compensation was not taken in consequence of 
 error, and because the debtor who might have taken the plea did 
 not know that his creditor owed a debt to him, and his want of 
 knowledge of this fact was excusable, or when, as the article says, 
 he had good grounds for being ignorant of the existence of the 
 
 claim . 
 
 In that case when he sues for the debt due to him he can 
 plead that, the privileges and hypothecs which attach to it are 
 still in force. The classical illustration is this: I pay you a debt 
 and I discover afterwards that you are debtor to a succession to 
 which I have succeeded. At the time of my payment I was not 
 informed that this succession had fallen to me. My ignorance 
 is, therefore, excusable. If your debt to the succession was secured 
 by hypothecs, etc., I am, in such a case, entitled to plead that 
 these securities have not been extinguished by my failure to set 
 up the compensation. (Pothier, Oblig. n. 639; Baudry-Lacant. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 3, nos. 1870 seq. See Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 400, note 5.) 
 
 Assignment. 
 
 Another illustration of the rule that compensation is not to be 
 allowed, to cause injustice to third parties who have acquired rights 
 is in the case of assignment. This is stated in C. C. E. 197/261: 
 A debtor who has consented to the assignment of a claim against 
 him. which is subject to compensation, may no longer set up 
 compensation as against the assignees, he can only enforce his 
 original claim against the assignor. (See C. A. Alex. 15 mai 
 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 379; C. A. Alex. 20 mars 1912, B. L. J. 
 XXIV, 203.) 
 
 The French Code adds: — 
 
 An assignment not accepted by the debtor, but of which due 
 notification has been given to him. prevents compensation only 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 513 
 
 of the debts due by the assignor posterior to such notification., 
 (C. C. F. 1295.) 
 
 This is another case of tacit renunciation of the right to claim' 
 compensation. By accepting the- transfer purely and simply, that 
 is, without making any reservation of his rights, the debtor agrees 
 to become debtor to the new creditor, and the new creditor ia 
 entitled to look to him for payment. If the debtor is going to 
 claim that he does not owe the debt or some part of it, this is 
 the moment for him to say so. If he does not say so now it 
 will be too late for him afterwards to maintain that he did not 
 owe the debt, because it was compensated with a debt which the 
 old creditor owed to him. But this result is not produced unless 
 there is an express acceptance on his part of the assignation. 
 The mere signification to the debtor of the assignment does not 
 prevent him from pleading that his debt is compensated in whole 
 or in part by one which the old creditor owed to him before the 
 signification. The signification, however, even without accept- 
 ance does, by the Mixed Civil Code as by the French Code, 
 produce this effect, that it prevents the compensation between his 
 debt and a debt which the assignor incurs to him after the signi- 
 fication. (C. C. M. 263.) By the Native Code an assignment 
 always needs the consent of the debtor. (C. C. E. 349/436. See 
 Halton, 2, p. 88.) 
 
 Arrestment. 
 
 An arrestment burs a compensation which could not have 
 come into operation until subsequently thereto. (C. C. E. 
 199/263; C. C. F. 1298.) After the arrestment the tiers-saisi 
 is not entitled to pay the debt to the creditor. He holds it for 
 the arrestor. If he were to compensate it with a debt subsequently 
 incurred by the creditor to him this would be in reality a payment 
 to the creditor. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1844; Laurent, 18, n. 429.) 
 
 Bankruptcy. 
 
 If after the bankruptcy of a trader one of his debtors acquires 
 a .claim against him, there cannot be compensation between these 
 debts. For, after the declaration of bankruptcy, all the creditors 
 of the bankrupt must be treated equally and paid proportionately. 
 To allow one of them to pay himself by compensation would be 
 to give him a preference over the other creditors. Accordingly, 
 the debtor of the bankrupt must pay his debt in full to the 
 syndic, and, as regards his claim against the bankrupt, he must 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 33 
 
514 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 present it, like other creditors, and take the dividend to which he 
 is entitled. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1845; Lyon-Caen et Renault, 
 Traite de Droit Commercial, 4eme ed. 7, n. 216; Thaller, Traite 
 Elem. de Droit Commercial, 4th ed. n. 1984; Cass. 22 oct. 1907, 
 D. 1907. 1. 508; C. A. Alex. 26 nov. 1913, Gaz. Trib. IV, 
 p. 38, n. 89; C. A. Alex. 1 mare 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 267.) 
 But this rule does not apply when the two debts both form part 
 of a current account between the parties. (C. A. Alex. 26 nov. 
 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 48. Cf. C. A. Alex. 25 fevr. 1914, 
 B. L. J. XXVI, 253.) The details belong to the commercial 
 law. (See C. A. Alex. 25 fevr. 1914, Gaz. Trib. IV, p. 105, 
 n. 255.) 
 
 Right to renounce compensation. 
 
 Where there are no rights of third parties in question it is 
 hardly open to doubt that the parties may, if they choose, renounce 
 a compensation which has taken place, and leave the two debts to 
 be enforced independently the one of the other. 
 
 Renunciation not being presumed, it will have to be clearly 
 established. 
 
 But that express renunciation is permissible would seem to be 
 sufficiently clearly shown by the fact that the code itself states, 
 as we have seen, two cases of tacit renunciation, viz., those given 
 in C. C. E. 197, 198/261, 262; C. C. F. 1295, 1299. (Baudry- 
 Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1867.) 
 
 The question whether a person may renounce beforehand the 
 right to plead compensation has been doubted, and it has been 
 argued that it was a matter of public order that parties should 
 not deprive themselves of this right. 
 
 In support of this argument reliance has been placed on the 
 rule that prescription cannot be renounced by anticipation. 
 (C. C. E. 80/108.) 
 
 But the two things are not really analogous. If it were possible 
 to renounce by anticipation the extinctive prescription of debts, 
 lenders of money would, as a matter of course, insist that their 
 debtors should become bound for ever. This would be extremely 
 against public policy. In the case of compensation it is 
 difficult to see that any public policy is involved. The prevailing 
 opinion is that the right to plead compensation may be renounced 
 by anticipation. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1881; Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 4, p. 394; D. N. C. G. art. 1293, n. 87.* Contra, 
 Toullier, 7, n. 393.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 515 
 
 (b) Facultative compensation. 
 
 When compensation by the sole operation of law is prevented 
 by any cause, the party in whose favour alone the cause of 
 objection exists may demand the compensation. And in such a 
 case the compensation takes place from the time of pleading the 
 exception only. Thus, if John owes William a debt which is not 
 exigible for three months, and William incurs a debt to John of 
 the same amount, the two debts are not compensated by operation 
 of law, because they are not equally liquidated and demandable. 
 But if John chooses to regard the debt which he does not owe 
 for three months as being already due, and if the term which has 
 been fixed is merely a delay in his favour, he is allowed to waive 
 it and compensation can take place. So if the person who has 
 been wrongfully despoiled of his thing, or if the depositor, or the 
 person whose claim is unseizable, chooses to waive his right to 
 prevent compensation there is no reason why he should not 'be 
 allowed to do so. (Demolombe, 28, n. 656; B.-L. et Barde, 3, 
 n. 1883; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, p. 371.) It would seem that 
 it is only a debtor whose debt is equal to or greater than the debt 
 which is due to him who can set up this kind of compensation. For, 
 otherwise, we should be allowing a debtor to make a part-payment 
 of his debt, which is contrary to the general principle of the law. 
 (C. C. E. 168/231; C. C. F. 1244.) It is true that the law 
 allows this in the case of legal compensation. (O. C. E. 193/257;' 
 C. C. F. 1290.) But this requires an express provision, and no 
 such provision as to facultative compensation is found in the code. 
 (Demolombe, 28, n. 664; B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1884. Contra, 
 Larombiere, on art. 1293, n. 14.) 
 
 Compensation in other laws. 
 
 The Swiss and the German codes do not admit legal compen- 
 sation operating automatically. There must he a declaration made 
 by the party invoking compensation. And, under both these 
 codes it is not necessary that the debt should be liquidated in 
 order to be set up in a compensation. (Code Fed. Oblig. 120 — 
 126; German Code, 387—396.) 
 
 Under the English law there is, likewise, no such tiling as legal 
 compensation. But if a defendant pleads a set-off or counter- 
 claim, the court may take account of the set-off. But the court 
 has discretion on the application of the plaintiff to refuse the 
 
 33 (2) 
 
516 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 defendanl permission to plead the set-off. (See Leake, Contracts, 
 6th ed. 735.) 
 
 (6) Confusion. 
 
 Confusion is the sixth mode of extinction of obligations. 
 ( onfusion is the uniting in one and the same person of the two 
 capacities of principal debtor and creditor of the same debt, 
 whereby both capacities become extinguished. Sureties are dis- 
 charged by confusion; co-debtors are only discharged in respect 
 of the contributive share of the debtor in whose person confusion 
 has taken place. (C. C. E. 202, 203/266, 267.) The Quebec 
 Code adds: The confusion which takes place by the concurrence 
 of the qualities of surety and creditor or of surety a)id principal 
 debtor does not extinguish the principal obligation. (C. C. Q. 
 1199. Cf. C. C. F. 1301.) 
 
 In these articles of the Egyptian Code there are a few verbal 
 changes, correcting the language of C. C. F. 1300 — 1301, but 
 the French law is the same as ours. The French Code says that 
 when confusion takes place the two debts are extinguished, but 
 this is evidently a mistake. In confusion there is no question of 
 two debts, as in the case of compensation, and, therefore, it is 
 more correct to say, as the Egyptian Code does, that the capacities 
 of the creditor and debtor are extinguished, or, as the Quebec Code 
 says, that confusion extinguishes the obligation, instead of the 
 two obligations. (C. C. Q. 1198; Demolombe, 28, n. 697; B.-L. 
 et Barde, 3, n. 1897. See Paris, 5 nov. 1901, D. 1902. 2. 89.) 
 
 Every obligation presupposes two parties, a creditor and a 
 debtor. 
 
 As soon as it comes about in any way that these two parties 
 become one and the Bame person, the obligation comes to an end 
 by confusion, or, at any rate, the right to sue is paralysed. A 
 man cannot sue himself. One cannot be one's own debtor. This 
 principle is of universal application and extends to real as well 
 as to personal rights. The moment a man becomes the owner of 
 a thing in which 'lie had previously a real right of a lesser kind, 
 the lesser right is swallowed up in the greater right of property, 
 or is confused with it. For example, if I hold a watch as a pledge, 
 and I afterwards become the owner of the watch, my previous 
 right of pledge is extinguished. A thing cannot be pledged to 
 its owner. If I have a hypothec over a house, and I become owner 
 cf the house, the hypothec comes to an end, or is paralysed. 
 Aubrv et Ran. 5th ed. ■">. p. 812; B.-L. el de Loynes, Privileges 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 517 
 
 et Hypotheques, 3, n. 2253; C. A. Alex. 30 nov. 1915, B. L. J . 
 XXVIII, 32.) Likewise, if I have a right of way over a field, 
 and I become owner of the field, the right of way is extinguished:, 
 
 In regard to servitudes the rule is laid down expressly in the 
 French Code. (C. C. F. 705.) Every servitude is extinguished 
 when the land to which it is due and that which owes it are united 
 in the same person by right of ownership. And the same prin- 
 ciple applies to usufruct, in which case the term consolidation 
 is commonly employed instead of confusion. (C. C. F. 617; 
 B.-L. et Chauveau, Biens, n. 737.) 
 
 It is the same also with obligations of a personal kind. Che 
 debt is not extinguished in the same sense as it would be by 
 payment, or by compensation, or novation. It would be more 
 correct to say that the obligation is paralysed, for the reason that, 
 while the debtor and creditor are one and the same person, its 
 execution is impossible. But the debt still exists. One conse- 
 quence of this fact will be referred to later in speaking of the 
 case of the surety. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1905; 
 Demolombe, 28, n. 715; infra, p. 519.) 
 
 Confusion usually caused by succession. 
 
 When confusion of two obligations takes place this is almost 
 invariably due to succession, and to the fact that the creditor 
 becomes the heir or universal legatee of the debtor, or vice versa. 
 And, for this reason, confusion is less important in our law than 
 it is in the French law, because, as will be explained later, when 
 the succession is regulated by Mohammedan law, no confusion 
 takes place. What follows applies only to successions governed 
 by the French law, or by some laAv which agrees with it on this 
 point. For instance, a man makes a gift of an immoveable to 
 his son subject to the payment of certain annual charges. 
 
 On the death of the son, the father accepts his succession ^impli- 
 cit rr. He succeeds to the immoveable, but the son's widow has 
 the usufruct. The father cannot claim payment of the charges 
 from the widow; they formed a debt due by the son, and the 
 father as the son's heir is liable to pay his debts, and, therefore, 
 he would be both debtor and creditor. It is only to the extent of 
 the impossibility of enforcing payment of the debt that confusion 
 takes place. If my father owes me L. E. 1,000, and he leaves 
 me all his estate, or he dies intestate and I am his sole heir, and 
 I accept his succession without benefit of inventory, the debt is 
 
518 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 extinguished by confusion. If I succeed to half his estate then 
 half the debt, that is, in this case, L. E. 500, is so extinguished, 
 because by taking- half the estate I become liable for half the 
 liabilities. (C. C. F. 873, 1220; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 4, 
 p. 405.") But the confusion ceases to exist if, after his acceptance 
 of the succession, the heir is successful in challenging his accept- 
 ance on the ground of fraud, fear, or violence, or if a minor, on 
 the ground of lesion. (C. C. F. 783.) 
 
 And the confusion is likewise ended if the heir who has accepted 
 it is excluded from the succession as unworthy. (C. C. F. 
 727—729.) 
 
 And the same result would folloAv if the will which created the 
 confusion were set aside upon any legal ground. (Bauclry-Lacant. 
 et Barde, Oblig. 3, n. 1914.) 
 
 In all these cases the rule applies which is stated in C. C. Q. 
 1198: — 
 
 In certain cases when confusion ceases to exist its effects 
 cease also. (Planiol, 2, n. 602: B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1914; 
 Demolombe, 28, n. 740.) 
 
 No confusion when benefit of inventory. 
 
 - Confusion occurs only when the heir accepts purely and simply. 
 The object of benefit of inventory -is precisely to prevent the 
 confusion of the property of the deceased with that of the heir or 
 legatee. The estate of the succession is to be applied 'first in 
 payment of debts. 
 
 So, if my father dies owing me L. E. 1,000, and I am the sole 
 heir, and I accept, .subject to benefit of inventory, I am entitled 
 to claim payment of the L. E. 1,000 if his estate is solvent. 
 
 If it is not solvent, I rank equally with other creditors for such 
 a proportionate share as the estate can pay. There is no con- 
 fusion, for I remain always in the same position as a stranger 
 to whom my father owed L. E. 1,000. I never become debtor 
 to myself. (C. C. F. 802: Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 572. 
 and p. 588.) 
 
 Extinction of principal debt by confusion extinguishes 
 accessory debt. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: Sureties are discharged by confu- 
 sion. C. C. E. 203 267/ This is less clear than the French 
 article: La. confusion qui s'opere dans Ja personne du debiteiir 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 519 
 
 principal, profile a ses cautions; celle qui s'opere dans la personne 
 de la caution, rientraine point V extinction ck Vobligatixm prin- 
 cipal. (C. C. F. 1301.) 
 
 If the principal debt is extinguished by confusion, the accessory 
 debt of a surety necessarily falls to the ground, for, otherwise, 
 the surety who had paid the debt would have a recourse against 
 the principal debtor, to whom in his new character of creditor the 
 debt has been paid. For example, Kamel owes Zaky L. E. 100, 
 and Ahmed is surety for the debt; Zaky dies and leaves Kamel as 
 his heir. Kamel is now debtor in the L. E. 100 in his individual 
 quality, and creditor for the same amount in his quality as Zaky's 
 heir. If Kamel as heir were to sue Ahmed, Ahmed could plead 
 that the debt was extinguished by confusion. If Ahmed paid 
 Kamel in his quality of heir, he would have an action in recourse 
 against him in his individual quality as- the principal debtor. 
 
 If the surety succeeds to the principal debtor, or conversely, 
 tho accessory obligation is extinguished, because a man cannot 
 be surety for his own debt. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1907; Deimo- 
 lombe, 28, n. 724.) But as the French Code states in another 
 place, if the obligation of the surety is itself secured by some one 
 who is the surety of the surety, the confusion which takes place in 
 the person of the principal debtor and the surety does not destroy 
 the action of the creditor against the surety of such surety. 
 (C. C. F. 2035.) 
 
 This supports the doctrine that the effect of confusion is not 
 actually to extinguish the obligation but merely to paralyse it. 
 If it were extinguished altogether the accessory obligation of the 
 surety would necessarily fall. But it appears by this article that 
 the obligation of the surety is not extinguished; it survives for 
 the purpose of acting as a support for the obligation of the sub- 
 surety. (Baudry-Lacant. et Barde, 06%. 3, n. 1910; Demo- 
 lombe, 28, n. 735.) 
 
 And another confirmation of this view is found in the article 
 which says, co-debtors are only discharged in respect of the 
 contributive share of the debtor in whose person confusion has 
 taken place. (C. C. E. 203/267 : ; C. C. F. 1301.) When 
 there are joint and several debtors, and confusion takes place 
 between one of them and the creditor, this extinguishes only the 
 part of the debt for which that co-debtor was liable. 
 
 If confusion were regarded as a complete extinction of the 
 debt, like payment, all the debtors would be liberated. For 
 
520 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 instance, Kamel, Zaky and Ahmed are joint and several debtors 
 to Aly in a debt of L. E. 3,000. 
 
 Aly dies and Kamel is his heir. Kamel as heir can sue Zaky 
 and Ahmed, but only for L. E. 2,000. If he sued one of them— 
 say Zaky— for L. E. 3,000, and Zaky paid it, Zaky would have a 
 recourse against him for L. E. 1,000, namely, Kamel's share, and, 
 accordingly, the principle applies: Qui doit garcmtir ne peut 
 evincer. (B.-L. et Barde, 3, n. 1908; Demolombe, 28, n. 729.) 
 
 French law as to confusion does not apply in the case of 
 Mohammedan successions. 
 
 In regard to the liability of .the heir for the debts of the deceased, 
 there is an important difference between the Mohammedan law 
 and the French law. 
 
 Seeing that succession is in Egypt governed by the personal 
 statute, the question whether there is confusion between the estate 
 of the heir and the estate of the deceased is a question which must 
 be answered by the personal law applicable. 
 
 If the succession is to a French national, the French rules as 
 to confusion will apply. And in other cases, if the succession is 
 to a foreigner, not being a Mohammedan, and the heir by his 
 personal statute is personally bound to pay the debts, this per- 
 sonal law will govern the case. 
 
 But when the succession is to a Mohammedan no confusion 
 takes place. According to the French law, the fundamental rule 
 is that the heir who accepts the succession without benefit of 
 inventory continues the personality of the deceased. (Planiol, 3, 
 n. 1780, bis; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 373. See, for the 
 history of this rule in the French law and for a criticism of it, 
 articles by M. Saleilles in Bulletin de la Societe d 'etudes legisla- 
 tives, 1910, p. 296, and 1911, p. 56, and the discussions as to 
 reform in the same volume, 1910, p. 69, and 1911, p. 25.) 
 
 The heir succeeds to the assets and is liable to pay the debts. 
 
 There is complete confusion between his patrimony and that 
 of the deceased. 
 
 But the heir can avoid this result by accepting the succession 
 only subject to benefit of inventory. (Planiol, 2, n. 600; Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 9, p. 588.) 
 
 In the Mohammedan law all this is different. According to 
 that law, there is complete separation between the estate of the 
 deceased and the estate of the heirs. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 521 
 
 Before any division is made of the estate of the deceased it is 
 necessary to pay the debts, and if, owing to creditors not sending 
 in their claims, or otherwise, the distribution takes place while 
 there are debts still outstanding, each heir is liable to each creditor 
 of his ancestor to the extent of the assets which have come into 
 his hands for a share of the debts proportionate to his share of 
 the succession. 
 
 But the liability of the heir is limited to what he has received. 
 He is by law in the same position as the French heir who has 
 accepted, subject to the benefit of inventory, and, therefore, no 
 confusion takes place. (See Mohammedan Personal Laiv, Kadri 
 Pacha, trans. Sterry and Abcarius, sect. 583, and p. 172; Ibn 
 Abdeen, v. 4, p , 471, in fine ; Statut Reel, sect. 94; Native Code oi£ 
 Appeal, 20 nov. 1906, Mizaan al Eitedaal, 4th year, p. 41; article 
 by Abdel Hamid Badawy, Bey, Du principe qu'en droit Musid- 
 man la succession n'est ouverte qiiapres acquittement des dettes, 
 VEgifpte Contemporaine, 1914, p. 14, 21, 23, 30, and appendice, 
 p. 40; Wilson, Digest of Anglo-Mohammedan Law, 4th ed. 
 
 p. 224; C. A. Alex. 14fevr. 1900, B. L. J. XII, 130.) 
 
 • 
 
 (7) Prescription. 
 Acquisitive prescription and extinctive prescription. 
 
 This is the seventh and last of the modes of extinction of 
 obligations enumerated in the Egyptian codes. • 
 
 Prescription in the modern law has two senses which require 
 to be carefully distinguished from -one another. It is either: — 
 
 (1) A means of acquiring ownership or real rights by posses- 
 sion, provided the possession has certain characters; or 
 
 (2) A means of extinguishing an obligation by the inaction 
 of the creditor for a certain time fixed by the law . 
 
 The first is called acquisitive or positive prescription, and the 
 second extinctive or negative prescription. In the French Code 
 these two kinds of prescription are treated of in the same title, 
 and there are some conveniences in this, because there are a number 
 of rules which apply to both kinds of prescription. (Arts. 
 
 2219—2281.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code has a different and more logical arrange- 
 ment. It deals with positive prescription in a section by itself as 
 one of the modes of acquiring ownership and real rights. (C. C. N. 
 76—87; C. C. M. 102—116.) It has another section devoted 
 to extinctive prescription in the chapter which enumerates and 
 
522 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 explains the various modes of extinction of obligation . (C. C. N. 
 204—213; C. C. M. 268—277.) Some French authors adopt 
 this arrangement of treating of extinctive prescription in a separate 
 place from acquisitive prescription. (Pothier, Ohlig. n. 678; 
 Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 2, p. 475; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 142.) 
 It would greatly conduce to clearness if the term prescription 
 were confined to extinctive prescription, and if some other term, 
 such as usucapion, were used instead of acquisitive prescription. 
 
 Law of prescription based upon public policy. 
 
 The rules both of acquisitive and extinctive prescription are 
 founded upon considerations of public j)olicy. 
 
 The principle that a creditor who fails to bring an action to 
 enforce his right within a certain period fixed by law cannot 
 succeed in his action, if the debtor takes the plea of prescription, 
 is a principle which rests upon the same considerations of public 
 policy as those upon which acquisitive prescription is based. For 
 the sake of the general peace, and to prevent dishonest actions, 
 the law provides that after a certain length of time obligations 
 shall not be enforceable if the objection is taken that the right 
 has prescribed. Documents may be lost, witnesses may be dead, 
 or the recollection of events long past may have become dim. 
 But for the rule of extinctive prescription or, as it is well called 
 in the English law, the rule of " limitation of actions," it would 
 in many cases be impossible to defend oneself against an action 
 laid on facts alleged to have happened long ago. (Pothier, Obli- 
 gations, n. 679; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 27.) 
 It is for these reasons that the law comes to the aid of the debtor 
 by creating a presumption of payment. 
 
 When the time fixed by law for prescription has expired the 
 obligation is extinguished and a presumption, of discharge created, 
 if the debtor invokes prescription. (C. C. E. 204/268; C. C. F. 
 2219.) 
 
 Full explanation of acquisitive prescription belongs to 
 law of property. 
 
 This is not the place for a full discussion of the law of acquisitive 
 prescription. It has seemed convenient to state in general terms 
 its nature and effects, because it is important to bring out the fact 
 that acquisitive prescription and extinctive prescription rest upon 
 the same foundation of public policy, and many of the rules 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 52$ 
 
 which apply to one of them apply to the other also. They may 
 both be said to illustrate the very broad rule that the law helps 
 those who help themselves, or, as it is expressed in the old broeard,. 
 vigilantibus non dormientibus jura subveniunt. 
 
 Rules common to acquisitive and extinctive prescription. 
 
 The Egyptian Code says: The rules of acquisitive prescrip- 
 tion concerning the causes of interruption and suspension are also 
 applicable to extinctive prescription. (C. C. E. 205/269.) But 
 these are not the only rules which are similar in both cases. The 
 rules with regard to renunciation of prescription and to the mode 
 of calculation of the prescriptive period are the same. It may 
 be convenient to consider first these general rules which apply to- 
 both kinds of prescription before taking up extinctive prescrip- 
 tion specially. 
 
 The delays of prescription. 
 
 The delays fixed in the Egyptian codes are taken from the 
 Mohammedan law, and are, in general, shorter than those of the 
 French law. 
 
 Long prescription. 
 
 Subject to the exceptions hereinafter mentioned, and those 
 specified by the law in particular cases, the term of prescription 
 for obligations is fifteen years. (C. C. E. 208/272.) 
 
 The maximum delay of prescription is fifteen years, except 
 in regard to ivalcfs and successions, in which cases there is a long? 
 prescription of thirty-three years. (JReglmwnt sur les Mehkemehs 
 of July 3rd, 1910, hi, n. 31, s. 376; Kadri Pacha, Statut Reel r 
 arts. 151 in fine, 152. See C. A. Alex. 23 fevr. 1905, B. L. J. 
 XVII, 123; C. A. Alex. 30 mars 1899, B. L. J. XI, 172; C. A. 
 Alex. 24 dec. 1914, B. L. J. XXVII, 84; C. A. Alex. 17 avril 
 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 310.) This long prescription in regard 
 to wakfs is for their benefit. It cannot be invoked against them by 
 a creditor. (C. A. Alex. 15 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 134.) 
 
 The fifteen years' prescription of the Egyptian Code corresponds- 
 to the thirty years' prescription of the French Code. It is taken 
 from the Mohammedan law. (Kadri Pacha, Statut Reel, art. 
 256.) 
 
 The public policy here is mainly to prevent contests which. 
 arise long after the obligation was formed. 
 
 The reason for the extinctive prescription is much the same as 
 
521 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 that for the acquisitive prescription. The creditor who has 
 remained inactive for so long a period is regarded as having lost 
 his right. There is a presumption of payment. (C. C. E. 
 204/268; C. C. F. 2219.) 
 
 Prescription of five years. 
 
 The term of prescription for rents, instalments, allowances for 
 maintenance, payments for hire and interest, and, in general, any 
 sums payable by the year or at shorter recurring intervals, is 
 five years, reckoned according to the Arab calendar. (C. C. E. 
 211/275.) 
 
 This prescription applies only to regular payments of a fixed 
 sum at periodical intervals. The courts insist on the two qualities 
 of regularity and periodicity. (Laurent, 32, n. 435; B.-L. et 
 Tissier, Prescription, n. 773, and n. 786; Req. 20 fevr. 1911, 
 D. 1913. 1. 364. See Riom, 17 avril 1907, D. 1907. 2. 376.) 
 
 The prescription is taken from the French law. (C. C. F. 
 2277.) 
 
 The motive of public policy which underlies it is not quite the 
 same as in the long prescription. It is based not so much upon 
 the presumption of payment as upon the principle that periodical 
 payments of this kind are expected to be met out of revenue. 
 If the creditor is so negligent as not to sue for them for five years 
 it would not be fair to compel the debtor to pay what might be a 
 large capital sum. It is not so much that the law presumes the 
 creditor has been paid as that it punishes him for his negligence. 
 (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 768. See C. A. Alex. 12 dec. 
 1889, B. L. J. II, 209.) Even a debtor who admits that he 
 has not paid the debt may, nevertheless, invoke this prescription. 
 (B.-L. et Tissier, op. cit. n. 769; Rouen, 11 aout 1890, D. 91. 
 5. 407; C. A. Alex. 3 janv. 1895, B.L.J. VII, 73.) 
 
 Restitution of fruits not governed by five years' 
 prescription. 
 
 The possessor in bad faith called upon to restore the property 
 together with the fruits or revenues which he had received during 
 his possession cannot plead that he is bound only to restore the 
 fruits of the last five years. If his possession has co t ntinued for 
 fifteen years or more he must account for the fruits for fifteen 
 years. Upon this point the Egyptian courts adopt the rule which 
 has been followed in France. (C. A. Alex. 20 mai 1897, B.L.J. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 525 
 
 IX, 357; C. A. Alex. 27 janv. 1892, B. L. J. IV, 80; C. A. 
 27 mars 1912, O. B. XIII, n. 92; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 
 3rd ed. n. 791; Aubry et Rau, 5th cd. 2, p. 568; Cass. 21 juiu 
 1897, D. 98. 1. 35; D. N. C. C. art. 2277, nos. 213, 214. 
 Centra, C. A. 22 dec. 1910, 0. B. XII, n. 50.) 
 
 There is no reason why the possessor in bad faith should be 
 allowed the benefit of the five years' prescription. His obligation 
 to restore the fruits is ancillary to his obligation to restore the 
 property itself. He never ought to have received any of the 
 fruits, and he was aware of this fact. He must restore every 
 piastre which he has received simply because he never ought to 
 have got anything. He must restore the fruits in a lump sum, 
 and it is a mere accident that he has received them annually. 
 There is no analogy between his duty to restore the fruits and 
 the payment of a sum payable by the year, to which alone the 
 five years' prescription applies. Accordingly, the Mixed Court 
 of Appeal has held that the term of prescription for rents is 
 established for the benefit of the lessee, and has no application to 
 a case in which rents have been received by a person who was not 
 entitled to them. (C. A. Alex. 25 mai 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 
 298.) 
 
 It is true that in one case the Native Court of Appeal pro- 
 nounced a decision in the contrary sense. The court held that 
 the object of this prescription was to penalise the negligence of 
 the creditor and to prevent the debtor from being unduly im- 
 poverished. They held that the claims for the fruits of property 
 wrongfully detained fell within the application of these principles, 
 and were therefore prescribed after five years. (C. A. 23 dec. 
 1910, O. B. XII, n. 50.) But this decision must be considered 
 as erroneous, and as overruled by the later decision of the same 
 court. (C. A. 27 mars 1912, O. B. XIII, n. 92, p. 68.) 
 
 The five years' prescription applies to moratory interest. 
 
 It is now the generally accepted view in France that moratory 
 interest which the law fixes as the damages for non-performance 
 of a money-debt, is governed no less than conventional interest by 
 this rule and prescribes in five years. (B.-L. et Tissier, Pre- 
 scription, 3rd ed. n. 785; D. N. C. C. art. 2277, n. 96.) 
 
 The language of the article under discussion in the Egyptian 
 codes is intended to express the same law. In so far as it differs 
 from the words of the French article, it is if anything 1 more 
 
526 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 favourable to the construction which would make it cover mora- 
 tory interest, for the Egyptian Code speaks of " payments for 
 interest " generally, whereas the French article refers only to 
 les interets des sommies pretees. (C. C. E. 211/275.) In France, 
 the point has been disputed, and there are old French decisions in 
 support of the view that moratory interest prescribes only by the 
 long period of prescription. (D. Rep. Prescription Civile, 
 n. 1080.) This view was taken in one case in Egypt by the 
 Mixed Court of Appeal. (C. A. Alex. 7 mai 1890, B. L. J. 
 II, 286.) 
 
 In favour of this opinion the following arguments are used: — 
 
 (1) The articles do not refer to moratory interest, and the word 
 "interest" must be construed narrowly as referring only to con- 
 ventional interest. The cases to which the five years' prescription 
 applies are all exceptions to the general rule, and, according to the 
 ordinary canon of interpretation, we must not extend by analogy 
 the number of exceptions. 
 
 (2) If we say that although the word " interest " does not cover 
 moratory interest this is immaterial, because moratory interest is 
 covered by the subsequent words: "in general any sums payable 
 oy the year or at shorter recurring intervals." The answer is 
 that this is not so. If a defendant is condemned to pay a capital 
 sum, plus the interest for all the years during which he has been 
 in delay, how can we say that this interest is a sum payable by 
 the year? It is paid as a lump sum together with the capital. 
 In fact, moratory interest is seldom paid in any other way than 
 this. 
 
 (3) Moratory interest is, as a matter of fact, not interest at 
 all in the strict sense of the term. When we say that a man is 
 liable to pay moratory interest, what we actually mean is that he 
 is liable to pay damages which are to be calculated in a certain 
 way prescribed by the law. What is called " interest " is in reality 
 ■damages for the non-execution of the contract. (D. Rep. vo. 
 Prescription Civile, n. 1080; Duranton, 21, n. 434; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 2277, n. 95.) 
 
 These arguments are not without considerable force, but on 
 the whole the sounder view appears to be that the articles intend 
 to cover moratory interest. 
 
 The reasons which have prevailed in France are: — 
 (1) The policy of the law in introducing a short prescription 
 for such payments is to prevent the debtor from being ruined by 
 the accumulation of interest added each year to the capital. And 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 527 
 
 it was also intended to penalise a creditor who negligently or 
 intentionally delayed for a long period to claim payment of his 
 debt. These reasons apply just as fully to moratory interest as 
 to conventional interest. 
 
 (2) Although in practice moratory interest is generally paid 
 in a lump sum, it is nevertheless true that moratory interest accrues 
 from year to year, and that each year's interest is a separate sum, 
 the right to which is not acquired by the creditor until the end 
 of the year. The creditor would have a perfect right to sue for 
 payment of the moratory interest for each year without suing 
 for the capital. 
 
 The true rule is that every accessory debt which accrues periodi- 
 cally to the principal debt is subject to this prescription. It 
 seems therefore that the Egyptian courts should follow what is 
 now the prevailing opinion on the subject in the French law. 
 (Rennes, 12 fevr. 1880, D. 80. 2. 221; B.-L. et Tissier, Pre- 
 scription, 3rd ed. n. 785; Colmet de Santerre, 8, n. 385, bis II; 
 Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 436; Colin et Capitant, 2, p. 145; 
 D. N. C. C. art. 2277, n. 96; De Hults, Rep. vo. Prescription, 
 n. 186.) 
 
 Prescription of 360 days. 
 
 The term of prescription is three hundred and sixty days for 
 sums due to physicians, advocates and engineers for their fees, to 
 tradesmen far goods supplied to private persons, to teachers and 
 instructors for money owing by their pupils, and to domestic 
 servants for their wages, even though new debts of the same nature 
 have arisen during such three hundred and sixty days. 
 
 The term of prescription for sums due to bailiffs and registrars 
 far the cost? of legal documents is likewise three hundred and 
 sixty days, running from the termination of the proceedings in 
 which such documents have been prepared, or, if no proceedings 
 have been commenced, from the drawing up of the documents. 
 (C. C. E. 209, 210/273, 274.) 
 
 This prescription corresponds roughly with some of the short 
 prescriptions of the French Code, but the periods in the French 
 Code are not the same in all these cases. (C. C. F. 2271 — 2272.) 
 The prescription here is based upon presumption of payment. 
 Obligations of this kind are commonly contracted without writ- 
 ing, and, frequently, when they are discharged by payment no 
 receipt is taken, or, if a receipt is taken, it is not preserved. 
 (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 741; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 
 
528 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 8, p. 447; Cass. 31 juill. 1899, S. 99. 1. 521.) Some points 
 in regard to the prescription of accounts consisting of a number of 
 items will be referred to later. 
 
 Debtor must be put upon his oath. 
 
 In cases ivhere the term of prescription is three hundred and 
 sixty days and under, the party invoking prescription shall only 
 be discharged if he declares upon oath that he is in fact liberated 
 from the debt. (C. C. E. 212/276. See C. A. Alex. 18 mars 
 1909, B. L. J. XXI, 257.) 
 
 Difference between French and Egyptian law. 
 
 In regard to the debtor's oath the Egyptian law is not the 
 same as the French law. 
 
 Under the French law the creditor may refer the matter to the 
 debtor's oath, but he is not obliged to do so. If the debtor refuses 
 to take the oath he will be condemned. If, however, the creditor 
 does not refer to the debtor's oath, the court is bound to give effect 
 to the plea of prescription. 
 
 No other proof can be admitted to show that the debt is still 
 owing. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 749; Aubry et Rau, 
 4th ed. 8, p. 447; Guillouard, Prescription, 2nd ed. 2, n. 782; 
 D. N. C C. art 2275, n. 2; Grenoble, 23 dec. 1898, D. 1903, 5. 
 572.) 
 
 Under the Egyptian law it is the debtor who is bound to take 
 the oath if he is to be liberated. It is not enough for him 
 to invoke prescription, he must supplement this plea by declaring 
 on oath that he does not owe the debt. (C. C. E. 212/276; Be 
 Hults, Rep. vo. Prescription, nos. 200 seq.) 
 
 Accordingly, if the creditor does not refer the matter to the 
 debtor's oath, and if the debtor does not offer to take the oath, but 
 contents himself with pleading prescription, it is the duty of the 
 court to call upon him to take the oath, and, if he fails to do so, 
 the court must condemn him to pay the debt. (Alex. 25 avril 
 1903, Role general, 3799, XXXIII; Sayour, Rep. n. 838. Cf. 
 ib. nos. 833—837.) 
 
 Serment de credulite. 
 
 Widoivs and heirs or their tutors shall declare .upon oath 
 that they do not know whether what is claimed is due. (C. C.-E. 
 213/277; C. C. F. 2275.) This last case is what is called the 
 serment de credulite. The debtor is dead, and it would not be 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 529 
 
 fair to call upon his successors to swear that their author had 
 paid the debt, because this fact may very well not be within 
 their knowledge. If the action was brought in the debtors life- 
 time, and in the court of first instance he did not take the plea 
 that the debt had been paid, his heirs cannot upon appeal avail 
 themselves of this plea. (C. A. Alex. 23 juin 1910, B. L. J. 
 XXII, 387.) 
 
 Prescription may be pleaded at any stage of the 
 proceedings. 
 
 The French Code contains an article which declares that the 
 plea of prescription may be set up at any stage of the proceedings 
 en tput etat de cause, and may even be pleaded for the first time 
 in the Court of Appeal. (C. C. F. 2224.) 
 
 There is no corresponding article in the Egyptian codes, but 
 it is clear that the law is the same. As regards the acquisitive 
 prescription, the party who has begun by founding upon some 
 other title of ownership, may at a later stage, and even in appeal, 
 plead that he is by prescription owner of the thing claimed., 
 This is not the introduction of a new demand, which is prohibited 
 in appeal by the Code of Procedure. (N. C. P. 368; C. C. P. M. 
 412.) The demand is still for the same object, viz., the property, 
 but it is made upon new grounds, and the addition of new ground's 
 is always permissible. (N. C. P. 369; C. C. P. M. 413; C. A. 
 Alex. 13 nov. 1884, Lantz, Rep. General, n. 874; C. A. Alex. 
 10 mai 1917, B. L. J. XXIX, 414.) 
 
 And as regards the plea of extinctive prescription, this is in 
 its nature a peremptory exception and can be made at any stage 
 of the proceedings. (C. A. Alex. 15 janv. 1914, B. L. J. XXVI, 
 154; Do Hults, Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 19.) But a party will 
 not be allowed to plead extinctive prescription when the circum- 
 stances clearly show that he has renounced that plea. And among 
 the circumstances to be considered will be his pleadings in the 
 suit itself. What facts amount to such a tacit renunciation of 
 the right to take the plea of prescription will be explained later 
 in speaking of renunciation. The rule itself is stated in the 
 French Code, and the Egyptian Code, no doubt, intends to retain 
 it. (C. C. F. 2224.) 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 34 
 
630 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The judge cannot ex officio give effect to prescription. 
 
 Seeing that the rules of prescription are based upon public 
 order, it might appear at first sight, that the courts ought to be 
 entitled to find that a right had been acquired or lost by the 
 expiration of the legal period, although this was not pleaded by 
 the party who would benefit by the prescription. But further 
 consideration shows that such a conclusion would be highly in- 
 equitable. The possessor may not choose to take advantage of 
 his right to deprive the owner of his property, or the debtor may 
 not wish to evade paying his debt though he has a legal excuse. 
 The law quite rightly respects these scruples. The French Code 
 says: Les juges ne peuvent pas suppleer d' office le moyen re- 
 sultant de la prescription. (C. C. F. 2223. See Cass. 17 mars 
 1897, D. 97. 1. 279; Req. 23 janv. 1901, D. 1901. 1. T02.) 
 The Egyptian Code, speaking of extinctive prescription, says that 
 it extinguishes the obligation if the debtor invokes prescrip- 
 tion, as the Native Code expresses it, or in the language of the 
 Mixed Code, when the parti/ bound expressly relies upon it. 
 (C. C. E. 204/268.) There is no doubt that the rule in Egypt 
 is. the same as in France: L' exception de prescription ne peut pas 
 etre soidevee d' office. (C. A. Alex. 14 nov. 1907, B. L. J. 
 XX, 7.) 
 
 According to the French law it is not necessary that prescrip- 
 tion should be expressly pleaded if the conclusions of the party 
 sufficiently show that he is in effect setting up the plea of pre- 
 scription. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 42; Cass. 
 3 aout 1870, S. 71. 1. 72, Journal du Palais, 71, p. 197; D. N. 
 C. C. art. 2223, n. 20.) 
 
 In Egypt, under the Native Code, this would no doubt be so 
 also, and, probably, the words of the Mixed Code, "When the 
 party bound expressly relies upon it," would not be interpreted 
 so literally as to make it indispensable that the word " prescrip- 
 tion " should be used. 
 
 Calculation of prescriptive period. 
 
 Although the Egyptian codes are silent upon the matter, there 
 is no reason to doubt that they intend to retain the traditional 
 principle of the French law that the period of prescription is to 
 be reckoned from the beginning of the first complete day after 
 the day upon which possession has been acquired in the case of 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 08 1 
 
 acquisitive prescription, or after the day upon which the right 
 of action has accrued in the case of extinctive prescription. See 
 C. A. Alex. 2-4 dec. 1914, B. L. J. XXVII, 84; 0. A. Alex. 
 7 mars 1901, B. L. J. XIII, 187.) The law reckons tinie by 
 days and not by hours or minutes. It is, as a rule, easy to preserve 
 evidence of the date of the transaction, but if it were necessary 
 to prove the hour of the day, innumerable difficulties would arise 
 from the differences of local time or the variations between time- 
 pieces. 
 
 The day upon which the right is acquired, whether it be the 
 right of possession or the right of action, is necessarily an incom- 
 plete day. If the right were acquired, for instance, at ten o'clock 
 in the morning, and the prescriptive period were five years, that 
 period would not run out until ten o'clock in the morning on the 
 corresponding day of the month five years thereafter. In order 
 to prevent such troublesome calculations, the Roman law and the 
 French law which was based upon it, laid down the rule that the 
 dies a quo was not to be reckoned in calculating the period of 
 prescription. 
 
 The period was to begin to run from the first moment of the 
 day after. And it is a further consequence of the rule that time 
 is reckoned by days, that the prescriptive period does not expire 
 until the last moment of the last day of the term. These rules 
 are laid down in two articles of the French Code: 
 
 La prescription se corrupt e par jours et non par heures. Elle 
 est acquise lorsque le dernier jour du terme est accompli. (C. C. F. 
 2260, 2261.) 
 
 Accordingly, if the possession has been begun, or the right of 
 action has been acquired, on the 29th of July, 1914, prescription 
 does not begin to run until the first minute of the 30th of July, 
 and if the prescriptive period is fifteen years, it will not be com- 
 plete until the first minute of the 30th of July, 1929. 
 
 Official holidays are included in the delay. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th ed. 2, p. 480; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 583; Guil- 
 louard, Prescription, 1, n. 88.) There is no doubt that the Egyp- 
 tian codes intend to retain these rules. (C. A. Alex. 17 dec. 
 1908, B. L. J. XXI, 78; C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 1913, B. L. J. 
 XXVI, 113; De Hurts, Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 67; Halton, 
 1, 203.) 
 
 34 (2) 
 
532 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Point of departure of extinctive prescription. 
 
 Extinctive prescription depends upon throe conditions: — 
 (1 A right of action accrued, that is, the obligation must be 
 exigible before the action upon it begins to prescribe; 
 
 (2) No action raised; and 
 
 (3) The lapse of the period fixed by law without the prescrip- 
 tion being interrupted. (Pothier, Obligations, n. 680; Aubry 
 et Rau, 5th ed. 2, p. 482; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, nos. 381, 
 384; D. N. C. C. art. 2261, n. 3.) 
 
 So long as the creditor has no right of action it would be 
 unreasonable to infer from his inaction any intention to abandon 
 his right, and, as will be explained later, the same principle applies 
 to the case in which, though the right of action has accrued, the 
 creditor cannot exercise it for a reason which suspends the pre- 
 scription. Accordingly, if the creditor's right is subject to a 
 suspensive condition or to a term, it will not begin to run until 
 the condition has been fulfilled or the term has arrived. These 
 rules are laid down expressly in the French Code: 
 
 La prescription ne court point : — 
 
 A Vegard (Tunc creance qui depend d'une conditio)/, jiisqvCa 
 ce que in condition arrive; 
 
 A Vegard d'une action en garantie, jusqu'd ce que V eviction 
 ait lieu; 
 
 A Vegard d'une creance a jour fixe, jusqua ce que ce jour soil 
 arrive. (C. C. F. 2257.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no such article, but it is not necessary, 
 as it is a logical consequence from the legal nature of prescription. 
 
 Pour que la prescription liberatoire puisse courir, it iaut que 
 ^obligation a laquelle elle se refere soil nee et exigible; si elle 
 depend d'une condition, on applique hi regie contra non valentern 
 agere non currit prescriptio; tel est le cas on le paiemeut dVun 
 legs depend du resultat d'un proces. (C. A. Alex. 13 mai 1909, 
 B. L. J. XXI, 342. Cf. C. A. Alex, ler mai 1895, B. L. J. 
 VII, 236; C. A. Alex. 2 mars 1910, B. L. J. XXII, 158; De 
 Hults, Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 160.) The rule is the same in 
 Mohammedan law. (Kadri Pacha. Statut Reel, art. 258, al . 1.) 
 
 Conditional debt. 
 
 The expression in the French Code -une creance qui depend 
 d'une condition — obviously refers to a Mi>pensive condition. The 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. -V!:', 
 
 creditor who has a right subject to a resolutive condition can 
 claim his right at once, and, therefore, prescription will run againsl 
 him if he does not do so. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 391 : 
 Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 132.) 
 
 Action in warranty. 
 
 The action in warranty which the French Code specially 
 mentions is merely an illustration of the general principle. The 
 vendor warrants the purchaser against disturbance in his enjoy- 
 ment. But the purchaser has no right of action against the vendor 
 until there has been an eviction, or what the law regards as 
 equivalent thereto. And, therefore, it is riot until this condition 
 has been fulfilled, that prescription begins to run in favour of the 
 vendor. As regards the action in warranty, there is controversy 
 as to what the law means by " eviction." In one view there is an 
 eviction when there is a disturbance of possession. (Aubry et Rau, 
 5th eel. 2, p. 484; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 393.) Accord- 
 ing to what seems the better view, the " eviction " only takes place 
 from the date of the final judgment pronouncing it. (Guillouard, 
 Prescription, 1, n. 135; Cass. 18 juill. 1876. D. 77. 1. 232.) 
 
 The Mixed Court of Appeal has decided iu this sens.e. C. A. 
 Alex. 24 mai 1910, B. L. J. XXII. 223. 
 
 Debt subject to term. 
 
 The same principle applies to the case where the deb: is sus- 
 pended by a term. The creditor cannot act until the term arrives, 
 and, therefore, this inaction cannot deprive him of any right. 
 (See Req. 9 janv. 1899, D. 1900. 1. 103.) Although the French 
 article refers only to a term of which the date is certain — une 
 creance a jour fixe — it is agreed that the same principle applies 
 to a term of which the date is uncertain, such as, for instance, a 
 debt payable when a third party shall die. (B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 390; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 138; Kadri 
 Pacha, Statat Reel, art. 258, al. 1.) 
 
 It is even more clear in this case than in that of the fixed date, 
 that the creditor has no right of action till the expiration of the 
 term. But we must not confuse with a debt subject to an uncertain 
 term a debt for the performance of which no time has been fixed, 
 but which is exigible when the creditor chooses to demand pay- 
 ment. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 1. c; Alex. 27 avril 1907, 
 Savour, Rep. n. 846.) 
 
534 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 It must be remembered that the granting of a term for payment 
 does not need to be made in express terms; it may be made, 
 tacitly, and the court, in many eases, is entitled to infer from the 
 circumstances that a term has been granted. 
 
 Prescription does not run till debt is exigible. 
 
 It may be a difficult question of interpretation to determine at 
 what momeni of time according to the intention of the parties the 
 debt became exigible. But this is a question of fact, the solution 
 of which d spends upon the particular circumstances. Proscription 
 docs not begin to run until the debt is exigible. B.-L. et Ti>>kt. 
 Prescription, n. 390; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 137. See 
 supra, p. 350.) 
 
 When the debt is divided into fractions or into separate 
 
 items. 
 
 When it has been agreed that a capital sum is. to be paid Ir- 
 regular instalments of a certain amount, each instalment is. for 
 the purposes of prescription, regarded as a separate debt. If I 
 borrow L. E. 5,000 from you, and it is agreed that I am to 
 •repay you at the rate of L. E. 1,000 a year, your claim to the 
 fifth instalment will not become exigible till the end of the fifth 
 year, and extinctive prescription would not be completed in my 
 favour as regards this instalment until the end of twenty years 
 from the date of the loan. Similarly, where rent is to be paid at 
 so much a month or a year, or according to some other unit of 
 time, or instalments of interest or wages of servants arc to be so 
 paid at stated intervals, each payment is regarded as a separate 
 debt. Pothier, Oblig. n. 679; Aubry et Rail, 5th cd. 2, p. 484; 
 Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 76; B.-L. et Tissier, Preservation, 
 n. 382: D. X. C. C. art. 2261, n. 11. 
 
 The same principle applies according to the Egyptian Nativti 
 ( ode i" sums due to physicians, advocates, and engineers for 
 their fees, In tradesmen lor goods supplied to private persons, to 
 teachers and instructors for money owing by Heir pupils, and to 
 domestic servants for their wages, even though new debts of the 
 same nature have arisen during such three hundred and sixty 
 days, that being in this case the prescriptive period. (C. C. E. 
 209." The Mixed Code does not mention advocates and engineers. 
 (C. C. M. 273. 
 
 These nil:- are of great practical importance. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 535 
 
 If goods are supplied by a tradesman upon a running account, 
 the receipt of each separate article would, but for such a provision 
 of the law, keep alive the whole debt, and the result would be that 
 customers would have to pay for items of debt alleged to have 
 been incurred years before, the accuracy of which it would be 
 impossible to verify. It is in the public interest that accounts of 
 this nature as well as rents, instalments and wages, should be 
 liable to a short prescription, and that persons should know that 
 if they allow such payments to get into arrears they do so at their 
 own risk. (Guillouard, Prescription, 2, n. 726, and n. 762; 
 B.-L el Tissier, Prescription, n. 722; Alex, ler avril 1905, 
 Sayour, Rep. n. 849.) In France, by recent legislation amending 
 C. C. F. 2272, the period of prescription as 10 sales by marchands 
 to particuliers has been extended to two years. (Loi 26 fevr. 
 1911.) 
 
 By "private persons" the Egyptian Code means the same as 
 the French Code means by the words particuliers non marchands 
 in the corresponding article. (C. C. F. 2272.) It means those 
 who buy goods not to sell them again, but to consume them. 
 
 And by " tradesmen " — marchands— the law means those whose 
 business it is to buy goods in order to sell them again either in 
 the same form or transformed by manufacture. 
 
 Tradesmen are such people as butchers, bakers, grocers, drapers, 
 confectioners, and the like. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 
 n. 722; Guillouard, Prescription, 2, n. 730.) A man whose 
 business it is to let out horses and carriages is not a tradesman. 
 (Trib. Civ. Seine, 24 janv. 1905, D. 1905. 5. 11.) 
 
 Hotel-keepers are not tradesmen. Nor is a building contractor 
 a tradesman, though it may be that he furnishes materials. For 
 this is merely accessory to his business, which is to do certain 
 work. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 724; Guillouard, 
 Prescription, 2, n. 733; Caire, 17 nov. 1913, Sayour, Rep. 
 n. 850.) 
 
 A manufacturer who has no shop but makes things for orders 
 is not a tradesman. (Caire, 6 avr. 1903, Sayour, Rep. n. 847.) 
 Nor is a barber a tradesman in this sense. He is an artiste, and 
 his claim for the amount due to him— often an abonnement for 
 shaving or hair-cutting— is not subject to this prescription. 
 (Trib. Civ. Bordeaux, 9 nov. 1903, D. 1904. 2. 187.) 
 
536 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Doubt with regard to sums due to physicians. 
 French law. 
 
 In France the principle is applied, with a certain difference, to 
 the case of physicians and surgeons. A doctor's account is gene- 
 rally calculated at the rate of so much a visit. If he is called in 
 to attend a patient, is he engaged at so much a visit, in the sense 
 that his fee for each visit forms a distinct separate debt which 
 has an independent period of prescription, just as each parcel of 
 goods sent by a tradesman to a customer creates a separate debt? 
 Or, is the true view that the doctor is called in to take charge of 
 a case, and that his account, when he sends it in, is a single account 
 by which he claims a lump sum for his services from the beginning 
 to the end of the case? The fact that the amount is fixed by 
 adding up the number of visits and assigning a certain fee to 
 each visit is immaterial. This is merely the professional way 
 of arriving at the amount which is considered as a reasonable 
 professional charge. According to custom this view is firmly 
 established in the French jurisprudence, and is in accordance with 
 a long settled tradition. (Chambery, 28 fevr. 1873, D. 73. 2. 
 153; Pothier, Oblig. n. 715; Planiol, 2, n. 656; B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 733; Guillouard, Prescript ion, 2, n. 720: D.N. 
 C. C. art. 2272, n. 89.) 
 
 Prescription does not begin to run against the doctor until the 
 case* is at an end by the patient dying or being cured, or by the 
 doctor being dismissed or giving up the case. If he is called in 
 again to attend the same patient for another illness this creates a 
 new debt. (Caen, 21 avril 1868, D. 71. 2. 180.) 
 
 Egyptian law. 
 
 It is more doubtful whether the same result can be reached in 
 Egypt upon the interpretation of the Egyptian Code. There is 
 a difference between the Native Code and the Mixed Code. The 
 Native Code classes together " physicians, advocates and en- 
 gineers,"' while the Mixed Code does not mention advocates and 
 engineers. (C. C. E. 209/273.) It might be argued that there 
 is a good reason for putting advocates and engineers in the same 
 class as doctors, seeing that they are commonly engaged to perform 
 not a single act but a series of acts. If, for purposes of prescrip- 
 tion, we are not to treat each visit of a doctor as creating a 
 separate debt, the same rule should apply to the case of an advocate 
 or an engineer who is called in to carry out a particular piece of 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 537 
 
 work, such as to conduct a litigation or to construct a bridge. The 
 French Code does in fact apply the same principle to avoues by 
 declaring that their action prescribes in two years a compter du 
 jugement du proces. (C. C. F. 2273.) 
 
 And the Egyptian Code does the same in regard to bailiffs and 
 registrars, when it says that the term of prescription for sums 
 due -to them for the costs of legal documents is three hundred and 
 sixty days ''running from the termination of the proceedings in 
 which such documents have been prepared." (C. C. E. 210 274.) 
 
 And it may further be said that the language of the Egyptian 
 codes "for their fees" is more naturally interpreted as meaning 
 a Lump sum than is the language of the French Code — Vaction 
 dcs medccins pour leurs visites. 
 
 The Mixed Courts would probably follow the rule of the French 
 jurisprudence in the case of physicians. 
 
 The Mixed Code, as we have seen, fixes the period of prescrip- 
 tion for sums due to physicians at three hundred and sixty days, 
 and is silent with regard to advocates and engineers. (C. C. M. 
 273.) 
 
 In the Mixed Courts it would be held, presumably, that pre- 
 scription does not begin to run against a doctor until his services 
 have terminated or until he has sent in an account, unless the usage 
 was to pay the doctor at the time, for each visit. This is not a 
 common practice. It is common for doctors to send in their 
 accounts annually, and it is reasonable to hold that unless the 
 account has been presented or the relation between doctor and 
 patient has terminated, there is no definite debt due. (De Hults, 
 Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 193.) 
 
 What rule would apply in the Native Courts. 
 
 Under the Native Code the short prescription of three hundred 
 and sixty days applies to "physicians, advocates and engineers." 
 (C. C. E. 209.) Under this article it does not seem possible to 
 make a distinction between physicians, advocates and engineers; 
 they are evidently classed together. 
 
 The question therefore comes to be whether we can apply to all 
 these classes of persons the same rule as the French jurisprudence 
 applies in the case of physicians. As already stated, one view is 
 that, just as a physician is engaged to take charge of a case which 
 involves a series of visits, so an advocate may be engaged to con- 
 duct a litigation, or an engineer to do a particular piece of work, 
 
538 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 and that the law regards the series of operations that may be 
 necessary as forming a single transaction. But against this con- 
 struction there are three- arguments : — 
 
 (1) The physicians, advocates and engineers are mentioned in 
 connection with tradesmen, teachers and domestic servants, and it 
 is said of all of them that the short prescription applies " though 
 new debts of the same nature have arisen during such three hun- 
 dred and sixty days." The intention appears to be that as soon 
 as a definite sum becomes due to any of these persons it is a 
 separate debt which prescribes in three hundred and sixty days. 
 
 (2) In regard to bailiffs and registrars it is said that the term 
 of prescription for sums due to them for the costs of legal docu- 
 ments is three hundred and sixty days, running from the ter- 
 mination of the proceedings in which such documents have been 
 prepared, or if no proceedings have been commenced, from the 
 drawing up of such documents. (C. C. E. 210/274.) 
 
 Upon the principle expressio unius est exclusio alterius we 
 cannot extend to the physicians, advocates and engineers, a favour 
 which is given by exception to bailiffs and registrars. 
 
 (3) The general rule of interpretation that in case of doubt 
 the construction shall be in favour of the debtor applies to this 
 case; and the shorter the prescription the better for the debtar. 
 
 Notwithstanding these arguments, it rather appears that the 
 courts might apply the French rule as to physicians, and extend 
 it to advocates and engineers when they were not engaged for a 
 single act. There is no "sum due" until the whole business is 
 completed. But the point is by no means free from difficulty. 
 
 Retroactive effect of prescription. 
 
 Prescription has a retroactive effect in favour of the person 
 benefited by the expiration of a prescriptive period. In the case 
 of acquisitive prescription, when the possessor has held for the 
 prescriptive period, he is in the same position as if he had been 
 owner during the period of his possession, and therefore he is not 
 obliged to account for the fruits. (Planiol, 1, n. 2708; B.-L. et 
 Tissier, Prescription, n. 103; D. N. C. C. art. 2220, n. 22.) 
 
 And in the case of extinctive prescription the debtor is not only 
 freed from the obligation to pay the capital sum, but also from 
 that to pay the interest which has been running. The law does 
 not regard prescription as a new title acquired at the expiration 
 of the prescriptive period. It presumes that the debt was dis- 
 charged at the date when the prescription began to run. (B.-L. 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 539" 
 
 et Tissier, Prescription, n. 103; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, 
 n. 51; Laurent, 32, n. 4, and n. 6.) 
 
 According to what calendar is the prescriptive period 
 reckoned? 
 
 In Egypt two calendars are in use, the Arab calendar and the 
 Gregorian calendar. When the codes speak of a " year," do they 
 mean a year according to the Arab computation or according to 
 the Gregorian calendar? There has been in the past much doubt 
 upon this point. The codes are entirely silent, and the juris- 
 prudence of the Mixed Court has been very conflicting. In the 
 Native Courts it has always been taken for granted that the Arab 
 calendar is intended. The Mixed Courts, after much hesitation, 
 have come round to the same view. The law may, pro- 
 bably, be regarded as now settled in this sense. (See Ch. Testoud, 
 article entitled Observations sur la mode de Calcul des Annies, 
 reprinted in I'Eyypte Contemporaine, 1916, p. 315; De Hults, 
 Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 68; Halton, 1, p. 203.) 
 
 In recent cases in which the question has arisen as to 
 extinctive prescription, the Mixed Court of Appeal has held that 
 the Arab calendar was to be applied. (C. A. Alex. 30 nov. 
 190-1, B. L. J. XVII, 26; C. A. Alex. 27 juin 1917, B. L. J. 
 XXIX. 490.) 
 
 And the same court has held that in the case of acquisitive 
 prescription the period should be computed according to the Arab 
 calendar, whether the possessor is a foreigner or an Egyptian. 
 (C. A. Alex. 4 avril 1895, B. L. J. VII, 214. See C. A. Alex. 
 2 fevr. 1893, B. L. J. V, 118; C. A. Alex. 24 fevr. 1892, 
 B. L. J. IV, 212.) 
 
 But it has been held that the delay of ten years for the re- 
 newal of a hypothecary inscription was to be calculated by the 
 Gregorian calendar. (C. A. Alex. 28 dec. 1898, B. L. J. XI, 69.) 
 
 The principal arguments in favour of applying the Arab calen- 
 dar are: — 
 
 (1) The periods of prescription being for the most part bor- 
 rowed from the Mohammedan law, according to which they were 
 of course calculated by the Arab calendar, it is to be presumed 
 that the legislator intended to continue them without change. 
 
 (2) The codes never mention the Gregorian calendar. 
 
 The Arab calendar is specially mentioned in regard to the term 
 of prescription for the periodical payments. (C..C. E. 211/275.) 
 It is referred to also in the Code of Criminal Investigation upon 
 
540 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 the question as to the calculation of prescription of a penalty. 
 (C. Crim. Inv. 276/271.) 
 
 (3) Doubts being interpreted in favour of the debtor, the Arab 
 calendar should be preferred, as under it the year is shorter. (See 
 C. A. Alex. 30 nov. 1904, B. L. J. XVII, 26.) 
 
 (4) If the legislator had intended to adopt the Gregorian 
 calendar he would have fixed the period for short prescription at 
 three hundred and sixty-five days instead of at three hundred 
 and sixty days, an arbitrary period which does not correspond with 
 either the Arab year or the Gregorian year. 
 
 (5) Where the Gregorian year is intended by the Egyptian 
 legislator, it is specially named, as in the Decree of 26 March, 
 1900, article 8, which provides that taxes shall prescribe in three 
 years according to the Gregorian calendar. (C. A. Alex. 17 dec. 
 1908, B. L. J. XXI, 78.) 
 
 Before this Decree the jurisprudence held that in this ease the 
 time was calculated by the Arab year. (C. A. Alex. 17 janv. 
 1895, B. L.J. VII, 89. Cf. Decree of 28 nov. 1904, lot n. 17, 
 art. 64. See Testoud, Observations sur la mode de Calcul des 
 delais an point de vue de la legislation Egyptienne, reprinted in 
 VEgypte Contemporaine, 1916, p. 315; Halton, 1, p. 203.) The 
 only serious argument on the other side is that we should apply 
 the rule cxpressio unius. Seeing that the codes in some instances 
 expressly mention the Arab calendar we must conclude that, when 
 they are silent as to which calendar is to be applied, they must 
 mean the Gregorian calendar. But this argument is not enough to 
 justify the conclusion- when we consider the arguments on the 
 other side. 
 
 Renunciation of prescription. 
 
 The French Code contains several articles on this matter which 
 apply both to acquisitive and to extinctive prescription. (C. C. F. 
 2220 seq.) The Egyptian Code has one article in the section upon 
 acquisitive prescription, stating the main rule, and two articles 
 in the section on extinctive prescription as to renunciation by an 
 insolvent debtor or by a joint and several debtor. 
 
 No one can renounce by anticipation his right to claim by 
 prescription. A person not subject to incapacity may renounce 
 a right to claim by prescription after it has vested. (C. C. E. 
 80 L08. < f. C. C. E. 206, 207/270, 271.) The principle 
 which governs this matter is one which applies to extinctive 
 prescription and to acquisitive prescription alike, and though we 
 are concerned here with extinctive prescription only, the principle 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 541 
 
 will he made clearer by explaining its application in both these 
 cases. The French law deals more fully with the subject, and 
 it is certain that the Egyptian legislator intends to retain the 
 French law. 
 
 Renunciation in advance is contrary to public policy. 
 
 In speaking of the nature of prescription in general, it has 
 been explained already, that the rules of proscription are based 
 upon considerations of public policy. It is in the public interest 
 to lix a period within which actions may be brought, and to 
 declare that if no action is brought within the stated period all 
 rights shall then be definitely determined. This purpose of the 
 law would be defeated if persons were allowed to deprive them- 
 selves by agreement of the right to claim the benefit of prescrip- 
 tion . 
 
 It would become common for creditors to insert conditions that 
 their right of action should not prescribe at all. And what 
 applies to a total renunciation applies to partial renunciation, 
 that is, to a prolongation of the legal period of prescription, such 
 as an agreement that the right of action shall prescribe in twenty 
 years instead of fifteen years. Such renunciations are expressly 
 prohibited by the codes. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. 
 n. 53, and n. 62; Planiol, 2, n. 649; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, 
 n. 318, and n. 321. Cf., however, Nancy, 16 nov. 1889, S. 91. 
 2. 161, and note by M. Bourcart.) 
 
 But although public policy requires that the right of action 
 shall expire within a certain period, it is not equally clear that 
 public policy requires that a creditor shall enjoy a right of action 
 for the normal period. If the creditor chooses to agree that unless 
 he brings his action within a certain period which is shorter than 
 the delay to which he would otherwise be entitled, there is nothing 
 in this which is contrary to public policy. (B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 96; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 323. Contra, 
 Planiol. 2, n. 648.) 
 
 The Egyptian law is no doubt the same as the French. Les 
 delais de prescription sont edictes dans un inter et de protection 
 sociale your mettre fin aux contestations, et dans ce sens, Us 
 tiennent a Vordre public; il pent etre loisible aux parties, pur un 
 accord entre elles, de faciliter les conditions de la prescription, 
 mais elles n'ont pas la faculte de les aggraver en stipulant d'avance 
 un delai plus long. (C. A. Alex. 22 fevr. 1905, B. L. J. XVII, 
 124.) 
 
542 THE LAW OK OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The German Code has an express declaration in the same sense 
 (art. 225). But in practice such an abridgment of the usual 
 period of prescription is rarely met with except in the kind of 
 contracts to which French writers give the name of contrats 
 & adhesion. These are those contracts in which there is no dis- 
 cussion of the terms between the parties. One of the parties 
 •dictates the conditions and the other has simply to take them or 
 leave them . See Saleilles, Declaration^ cle Volenti, p . 229 ; Planiol,; 
 2, n. 972.) For instance, a clause is frequently found in policies 
 of insurance which provides that unless the action is brought 
 within a short period, such as a year from the date of the loss, 
 the right of action shall expire. 
 
 According to the French jurisprudence such conditions are valid, 
 though there is no doubt that conditions of this kind lend them- 
 selves to abuse. (Cass. 2 fevr. 1898, D. 98. 1. 561; Cass. 4 dec. 
 1895, D. 96. 1. 241, and note by M. Sarrut; authorities cited by 
 B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 96, note 1; Colin et Capitant, 
 2, p. 150.) 
 
 Is the rule prohibiting renunciation an absolute one? 
 
 There is considerable French authority for the proposition that 
 in spite of the prohibition of renunciations of prescription, there 
 are, notwithstanding, certain cases in which an agreement to pro- 
 long the prescriptive period will be sustained by the courts. The 
 provisions of the code which lay down the period of the long 
 prescription or fix the quinquennial prescription for periodical 
 payments, are undoubtedly based upon public policy, and no re- 
 nunciation beforehand of the right to take advantage of these 
 provisions can be permitted. But this is by no means equally 
 clear in regard to certain of the short prescriptions of a more 
 . special kind. 
 
 If the law of sale says that an action on a warranty against 
 latent defects must be brought within eight days of the discovery 
 of the defect, it does not seem that there is any reason of public 
 policy which would exclude an agreement giving the buyer a 
 longer delay. (C. C. E. 324/402; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 
 n. 65; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 322. And it has been 
 held in France by the Conseil d'Etat that an agreement by which 
 the liability of the architect and the contractor was extended, 
 was not contrary to public policy. (Cons. d'Etat, 3 janv. 1881, 
 S. 81. 3. 34, D. 82. 3. 119.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 543 
 
 If the contractor, for instance, agrees that instead of being 
 liable for ten years he will be liable for twenty years for defects 
 in the building, this is surely in the interest of public policy. 
 And it does not appear that an agreement like this is such a 
 renunciation of prescription as the law intends to prohibit. 
 (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 65; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 5, 
 p. 677, note 30; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 322; D. N. C. C. 
 art. 1792, n. 294.) 
 
 Is an agreement to suspend prescription a renunciation 
 in advance? 
 
 The tendency of the French law is to interpret strictly the 
 prohibition on ne peut d'avance renoncer a la prescription. % An 
 agreement by the parties to suspend prescription for a certain 
 period is not a renunciation. If a party binds himself by an 
 agreement not to take advantage of the law of prescription during 
 a certain delay, his agreement does not fall within the prohibition 
 and is not against public policy. If, for example, the parties 
 agree to submit their differences to arbitration, they may naturally 
 and properly agree at the same time that during the arbitration 
 prescription shall be suspended. If an action had been raised 
 prescription would have been suspended during the action, and 
 why should a party who is willing to settle his dispute amicably 
 be discouraged by knowing that prescription is running against 
 him? (Toulouse, 18 mai 1868, S. 71. 1. 156, Journal du Palais, 
 71, p. 530; C. Cass, de Belgique, 7 oct. 1894, D. 96. 2. 169; 
 B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 63; Guillouard, Pre- 
 scription, 1, n. 323.) 
 
 It is for the courts to say when an agreement to suspend pre- 
 scription amounts to a prohibited renunciation. If there is a 
 sufficient reason in the circumstances for such a step the parties 
 will be allowed to stipulate the suspension. (B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 63; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 320.) 
 
 Renunciation of acquired prescription. 
 
 Public policy does not prohibit a person from renouncing a 
 right to claim the benefit of a prescription which he has acquired. 
 The law guarantees him the right, but when he has acquired it 
 he can dispose of it as of any asset of his estate. The codes 
 state this rule: 
 
 A person, not subject to incapacity may renounce a right to 
 
544 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 claim by prescription after it has vested. (C. C. E. 80, 108; 
 C. C. F. 2220.) 
 
 Renunciation during the course of prescription. 
 
 It is also permissible to renounce the benefit of part of a pre- 
 scriptive period which has elapsed. The Egyptian codes are 
 silent upon this point, but the French law is clear, and it is 
 expressly stated in the Civil Code in Quebec: Prescription 
 cannot be renounced by anticipation. That acquired may be 
 renounced, and so may also the benefit of any time elapsed by 
 which prescription is begun. (C. C. Q. 2184.) 
 
 A renunciation of this kind during the course of prescription 
 is. in the case of extinctive prescription, equivalent to an acknow- 
 ledgment of the right of the other. It is an interruption of pre- 
 scription. The person who has made the acknowledgment loses 
 the benefit of the time elapsed, but the" prescription begins to 
 run again in his favour. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 93; 
 C. A Alex. 11 janv. 1900, B. L. J. XII, 84. 
 
 And a tutor or curator who has power to pa}' the debt of the 
 ward may, by giving the creditor an acknowledgment of the debt, 
 prevent prescription being completed against him. (Pothier, 
 Oblig. n. 699; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 94.) 
 This point will be more fully considered under the head of inter- 
 ruption. (Planiol, 2, n.700.) 
 
 Renunciation may be tacit. 
 
 The French Code says that renunciation of prescription is either 
 express or tacit, and that la renonciation tacite resulte d'un fait 
 qui suppose V abandon du di-oit acquis. (C. C. F. 2221.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no similar article, but no doubt the 
 intention is to preserve the old law. The law does not prescribe 
 that renunciation shall be made in any particular form, and, 
 therefore, according to general principles, it may be inferred from 
 any conduct on the part of the person entitled to claim prescription 
 which clearly indicates his intention to renounce the benefit of the 
 prescription which has been acquired in his favour. 
 
 But there is always a presumption of fact against a man 
 gratuitously abandoning a right, and, therefore the court will 
 not be entitled to find that there has been a tacit renunciation 
 unless this is the only reasonable inference which can be drawn 
 from the facts proved. If his conduct, although suggestive of 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 545 
 
 renunoiation, is, nevertheless, reasonably capable of another ex- 
 planation, he will have the benefit of the doubt. (Aubry et Rau, 
 4th ed. 8, p. 452; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 334; Cass. 
 6 dec. 1899, D. 1901. 1. 299.) 
 
 Among the facts to be considered will be the pleadings in the 
 action, but, as we have seen, the plea of prescription docs not 
 need to be set up at first, and the fact that the defendant first 
 states other defences, such as the non-existence of the debt or its 
 payment, does not in itself amount to a tacit renunciation of the 
 right to plead prescription at a later stage. He may not have 
 known that he was entitled to the plea of prescription, or he may 
 have had conscientious scruples against relying upon a technical 
 rule of law so long as he thought that he might succeed upon other 
 grounds. (Planiol, 2, n. 701; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 
 3rd ed. nos. 51, 77; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 337; Grenoble, 
 12 janv. 1904, D. 1907. 2. 289. But see Paris, ler mars 1893, 
 D. 93. 2. 296. C. A. Alex. 19 janv. 1899, B. L. J. XI, 96.) 
 But the conduct of the party in appeal may be such as to point 
 unmistakeably to renunciation. (Req. 5 nov. 1907, D. 1908. 
 1. 132.) 
 
 It is not possible to lay down general rules as to what will 
 amount to tacit renunciation. The question is one which depends 
 upon the facts of each particular case. The facts relied upon must 
 be subsequent to the date when prescription was acquired, for, 
 otherwise, they would be unavailing. They might amount to a 
 renunciation of the period of prescription which had already run, 
 but no more. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 70. See Cass, 
 ler mars 1905, D. 1907. 1. 376; Grenoble, 12 janv. 1904, D. 
 1907. 2. 289.) 
 
 The following are examples of facts from which tacit renun- 
 ciation may be inferred. The payment of a debt which is pre- 
 scribed raises a strong presumption of renunciation of the pre- 
 scription. According to some writers it is so conclusive that even 
 if the debtor pays under protest, and subject to reservation of all his 
 rights, he will still be considered to have renounced the prescrip- 
 tion. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 71.) 
 
 But this appears to be unreasonable. 
 
 A payment on account is likewise a tacit renunciation of pre- 
 scription of the whole debt, unless the debtor declares at the same 
 time that he only admits liability to the extent of the amount 
 which he pays. 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 35 
 
546 TUB LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The payment of interest of a debt or of the arrears of an 
 annuity is a renunciation of prescription as regards the whole 
 liability, unless the debtor has expressly reserved his right. 
 (Poitiers, 30 juill. 1877, D. 78. 2. 60.) An acknowledgment 
 of the liability, a promise to pay the debt, a request to be allowed 
 time, the giving or offering of a security, the claim that the debt 
 has been paid by compensation, the agreement to submit to a 
 compromise, are facts from which renunciation will be inferred 
 unless the debtor reserved his rights. (Guillouard, Prescription, 
 1, nos. 335 seq.: B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, 3rd ed. nos. 71 
 seq.; D. N. C. C. ,art. 2221, nos. 10 seq.- Cass. 3 mars 1885, 
 S. 86. 1. 360; Cass. 6 juin 1896, S. 97. 1. 407; C. A. Alex. 
 11 janv! 1900, B. L. J. XII, 84; C. A. Alex. 31 janv. 1901, 
 B. L. J. XIII, 132.) On the other hand, the declaration by the 
 debtor that he does not owe the debt, or an offer to pay what he 
 shall be found to owe after an investigation of the accounts does 
 not amount to renunciation. 
 
 Tacit renunciation must be en connaissance de cause. 
 
 Renunciation is the voluntary abandonment of a right, and 
 a person cannot renounce a right unless he knows that it exists. 
 Accordingly,* if it appears that although prescription has been 
 acquired the debtor was unaware of this fact, his conduct may not 
 be held to prove renunciation of the right to claim prescription., 
 (Orleans, 16 fevr. 1865, D. 65. 2. 60.) 
 
 But it does not follow from this that a debtor who has paid a 
 debt against which he might have pleaded prescription, can recover 
 what he has paid by proving that he was ignorant of his right to 
 claim prescription. He has made a voluntary payment in dis- 
 charge of an obligation, and what the creditor has received was 
 legally due to him. The debt was not extinguished ipso jure by 
 the lapse of the prescriptive period; it might have been extin- 
 guished if the debtor had invoked prescription, but as he did not 
 do so, there was a subsisting debt, not a natural debt but a civil 
 debt, and the payment accordingly was not a case of payment of 
 something not due, nor was it a payment in error of a natural 
 obligation. The right of repetition, therefore, does not exist. 
 (B.-L. et Tissier, 3rd ed. n. 71, and n. 104.) The German Code 
 takes this view. (Art. 222; see not^ by M. Saleilles. In this 
 sense, Trib. Suram. Muski, 18 mars 1906, O. B. VII, n. 68. 
 Contra, Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 335.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 547 
 
 Renunciation of prescription is not an alienation. 
 
 It might appear at the first glance that the person who renounces 
 his right to claim a prescription which has run in his favour 
 thereby effects an alienation of property/. But this is not an exact 
 view of the matter. The possessor who has had a sufficient pos- 
 session does not become the owner of the property until he has 
 invoked the prescription. And the debtor whose creditor has 
 remained inactive during the prescriptive period is not liberated 
 from his liability until he has invoked the prescription. Pre- 
 scription does not operate ipso jure. 
 
 The right in the case of acquisitive prescription is a right to 
 claim by prescription. (C. C. E. 80/108.) And in the case 
 of extinctive prescription the obligation is extinguished if the 
 debtor invokes prescription. (C. C. E. 204/268.) From this 
 principle it follows that the renunciation of the claim does not 
 constitute an alienation. Upon this point the Egyptian Native 
 Code is clearer than the French Code, for the French Code says: — 
 La renonciation tacite resulte d'un fait qui suppose Vabandon 
 4u droit acquis. (C. C. F. 2221.) And it has been maintained 
 that the expression droit acquis implies a right of property. But 
 it is generally admitted by French writers that this is not so. 
 
 The droit acquis is not the property but the right to set up the 
 plea of prescription. (Planiol, 1, n. 2714; B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 82; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 324.) The 
 Mixed Code uses the rather ambiguous phrase renounce a pre- 
 scriptive right. (C. C. M. 108.) But the Native Code with 
 greater precision speaks of the right to claim by prescription. 
 (C*. C. E. 80.) 
 
 The distinction between a renunciation and an alienation has 
 important practical consequences. The renunciation is a unilateral 
 act which does not need any acceptance. (C. A. Alex. 25 mai 
 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 365.) The possessor who renounces his 
 right to claim an immoveable does not thereby create a new title 
 which requires registration, and a renunciation of acquired pre- 
 scription, whether acquisitive or extinctive, is not a gift, and 
 therefore is not subject to the rules as to gifts. The person who 
 renounces his right to claim prescription does not make a gift 
 which is offered to him by the law. (Bufnoir, Propriete et Con- 
 trat, p. 164; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 83. See, however, 
 Cass. 22 juill. 1895, D. 96. 1. 569.) 
 
 35 (2) 
 
548 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Renunciation of the right to claim acquisitive 
 prescription requires capacity to alienate. 
 
 Although the renunciation is not, strictly speaking, an aliena- 
 tion, it is a dangerous act. If it does not make the person poorer 
 it prevents him from becoming richer, as he would have been if 
 he had availed himself of his right to claim 'the prescription. 
 Accordingly, the right to renounce is given only to persons having 
 capacity to alienate. A person not subject to incapacity may 
 renounce a right to claim by prescription after it has vested. 
 (C. C. E. 80.) Any person, who is sui juris, may renounce a 
 prescriptive right already acquired. (C. C. M. 108.) Celui 
 qui ne peut aliener ne pent renoncer a la prescription acquise, 
 (C. C. F. 2222.) So in the French law minors and interdicted 
 persons, or their tutors acting alone, cannot renounce a prescrip- 
 tion. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 87; D. N. C. C. art. 
 2222, n. 5.) 
 
 And in the Mohammedan law such a renunciation, being neces- 
 sarily injurious, would be absolutely null. (Mohammedan Per- 
 sonal Law, Kadri Pacha, s. 484.) Whether a tutor or other 
 administrator may renounce a prescription if he complies with 
 the formalities which would be necessary for an alienation, is a 
 much disputed question in the French law. According to one 
 view, to make a gratuitous aliejnation can never be within the 
 powers of an administrator. (Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 327; 
 Aubry et Eau, 5th ed. 1, p. 712; Laurent, 32, n. 202.) But, 
 surely, the minor is sufficiently protected by the formalities re- 
 quired for an alienation. And why in the case of extinctive pre- 
 scription when the tutor knows that the debt has not been paid 
 should be compelled to allow his ward to be unjustly enriched by 
 escaping the necessity of paying it? (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescrip- 
 tion, 3rd ed. n. 87; D. N. C. C. 2222, nos. 12 seq.) 
 
 Capacity for renunciation of extinctive prescription. 
 
 The codes are silent upon this point, but it is clear that the 
 debtor who declines to avail himself of the prescription which has 
 run in his favour, does not alienate anything. He simply consents 
 to be liable as he was before. The capacity on his part which is 
 required for such a consent must, accordingly, be the same as the 
 capacity to contract an obligation affected by the prescription. 
 If he has the capacity to make Buch a contract, he has the capacity 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 549 
 
 to agree to continue to be liable under it. '(B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 88; Aubry et Rau, 4th ed. 8, p. 452; 
 Bordeaux, 31 dec. 1895, D. 97. 2. 97, note 2.) 
 
 Right of creditors and other third parties to revoke a 
 prescription which has been renounced. 
 
 Extinctive prescription may be invoked by the other creditors 
 of a person bound by an obligation, even when 'the latter has 
 renounced the benefit thereof, if such renunciation has bean made 
 in fraud of their rights. '(0. C. E. 206/270; C. C. F. 2225.) 
 
 There are two questions which may arise in regard to the right 
 of creditors. If their debtor owes a debt which has prescribed, 
 but he does not take the plea of prescription and remains inactive, 
 can his creditors take the plea for him in virtue of the oblique 
 action? It might be argued that his right to plead prescription 
 is a purely personal right depending upon moral considerations. 
 If he believed himself bound in honour to (pay the debt his creditors 
 could not set up the plea of prescription, according to the general 
 principles which apply to the oblique action. (C. C. E. 141/202. 
 See supra, p. 100.) 
 
 The article under consideration intends to remove this doubt 
 by declaring that the creditors can act in their debtor's place if 
 he refuses to do so. The right to plead prescription is not a right 
 which is "purely personal" to the debtor. (B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, 3rd ed. n. 111.) 
 
 Again, if the debtor has expressly renounced the prescription, 
 or has tacitly renounced it by his conduct, have his creditors the 
 right to set aside the renunciation by the Paulian action? Further, 
 if so, do they need to prove that the renunciation by their debtor 
 was in fraud of their right? Or is it sufficient to prove that the 
 renunciation was to their prejudice? The general rule of the 
 Paulian action is that creditors can procure the avoidance of the 
 abandonment of a right to their prejudice without proof of fraud. 
 (C. C. E. 143/204. See supra, p. 108.) 
 
 The present article makes it clear that the renunciation of pre- 
 scription is a special kind of abandonment of a right as to which' 
 the creditors must prove both facts, viz., that it was to their 
 prejudice, and that it was in fraud of their rights. If the debtor 
 renounces the benefit in good faith and honestly, his creditors 
 have no remedy. (Halton, 1, p. 394. See, however, De Hults, 
 Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 34.) 
 
550 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 The French article is not clear upon this point, and there is 
 controversy in the French law about it. (B.-L. et Tissier, Pre- 
 scription, n. 114; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 344; Planiol, 1, 
 n. 2716; D. N. C. C. art. 2225, n. 16.) According to most 
 authorities and to the most recent jurisprudence the creditors do 
 not need to prove fraud, but they must prove that the renunciation 
 a cause un prejudice au.r creanciers en creant ou en augm&nicent 
 Vinsolvabilitc de lew debiteur. It will generally be easy for 
 them to prove this. (Cass. 23 juill. 1912, D. 1914. 1. 30.) 
 
 Can parties other than creditors sometimes invoke 
 prescription which has been renounced? 
 
 Upon this point the French article says, creditors or any other 
 person having an interest in prescription being acquired maty set 
 up the plea. (C. C-. F. 2225.) A surety, for example, may 
 set up the prescription which his principal has renounced, or a 
 co-debtor the prescription which has been renounced by his fellow- 
 debtor. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 106; Guillouard, 
 Prescription, 1, n. 309. See Cass. 13 fevr. 1911, D. 1911. 1. 
 391.) 
 
 The benefit of prescription exists by law in favour of these 
 persons each of whom 1 has a proper right of his own, distinct from 
 the right of the principal debtor or of the co-debtor respectively. 
 
 So far as these cases are concerned the Egyptian Code is more 
 explicit than the French Code. 
 
 A renunciation by one of severed persons liable jointly and 
 severally, or by a person liable as principal, does not prejudice the 
 rest of the persons bound jointly with him, or his surety, if they 
 are entitled to set up prescription on their own account. (C. C. E. 
 207/271.) But it is generally agreed that in the French law 
 these are not the only cases. C. C. F. 2225 applies also to other 
 persons having an interest in setting up prescription. 
 
 Probably the Egyptian Code in referring specially to the 
 surety and the co-debtor, does not intend to exclude such other 
 persons. An example would be that of a person who has granted 
 a hypothec to secure the debt of another. (De Hults, Rep. vo. 
 Prescription, n. 38.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 551 
 
 Interruption of prescription. 
 
 A prescription which is in the course of running may be inter- 
 rupted, that is to say, a fact may occur which renders useless for 
 the purposes of prescription, the time which has already expired. 
 
 In regard to acquisitive prescription this may happen in either 
 of two ways: — 
 
 (1) If the possessor loses his possession, in which case there 
 is said to be a natural interruption of prescription; or 
 
 (2) If the owner makes a demand upon the possessor to give 
 up his possession, in which case there is said to be a civil inter- 
 ruption. 
 
 In regard to extinctive prescription there can be no cmestion 
 of loss of possession, and the only kind of interruption possible 
 is civil interruption. Extinctive prescription is based upon the 
 inaction of the creditor. If this inaction comes to an end by his 
 claiming his right in certain formal ways, the prescription is 
 interrupted, and, further, an acknowledgment on the part of the 
 debtor of the right of the creditor interrupts the prescription. 
 But it is only the creditor whose action interrupts the prescription 
 which is running against him. He cannot claim that the pre- 
 scription was interrupted by some legal proceeding at the instance 
 of a third party. (C. A. Alex. 26 dec. 1912, B. L. J. XXV, 
 88; C. A. Alex. 3 avril 1912, B. L. J. XXIV, 248.) 
 
 Acts of interruption. 
 
 (1) A" citation to appear is a distinct claim by the owner which 
 interrupts prescription, and, according to the Egyptian jurispru- 
 dence, this is so even if the citation is to appear before an incom- 
 petent court. The French article says so in express terms. 
 (C. C. E. 82/111; C. C. F. 2246; C. A. Alex. 23 mars 1911, 
 
 B. L. J. XXIII, 237; C. A. Alex. 12 janv. 1911, B. L. J. 
 XXIII, 105; C. A. Alex. 30 mai 1895, B. L. J. VII, 314;) 
 
 C. A. Alex. 11 dec. 1902, B. L. J. XV, 43.) 
 
 It has also been held in Egypt that a citation interrupts pre- 
 scription, although the citation is null in point of form. (C. A. 
 Alex. 12 janv. 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 105. Contra, De Hults, 
 Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 99.) The French Code lays down the 
 opposite rule as to this, but this is disapproved of by some writers 
 as being difficult to reconcile with the preceding article, and as 
 
552 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 making the party suffer for -the fault of the huissier. (Planiol, 1, 
 n. 2691. Contra, Aubry ct Ran, 5th ed. 2, p. 507.) A citation 
 null in point of form is just as much a declaration of intention 
 to make the claim as a citation before an incompetent court. As 
 the Egyptian Code is silent there is no reason for npt applying 
 the same rule in both cases. (C. C. F. 2247.) If the action is 
 dismissed, the interruption is as if it had never taken place— k 
 regardee comme non avenue. (C. C. F. 2247; B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 504; C. A. Alex. 18 mai 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 
 330.) But mere declarations or protests do not interrupt pre- 
 scription. (C. A. Alex. 12 mars 1913, B. L. J. XXV, 223.) 
 Nor is prescription interrupted as against X by the fact that in an 
 action by A against B, B reserves all his rights of recourse! 
 against X. (C. A. Alex. 29 oct. 1918, B. L. J. XXXI, 4. 
 
 (2) A monition of execution in proper form, even though not 
 followed up, likewise interrupts prescription. The jurisprudence 
 applies the same rule to other acts of execution, such as a saisie- 
 arret. (C. A. Alex. 29 fevr. 1889, B. L. J. I, 72; C. A. Alex. 
 12 janv. 1915, B. L. J. XXVII, 109; Halton, 1, p. 208.) 
 Naturally, if the plaintiff allows his action to be extinguished 
 by peremption it is as if it had never occurred. (C. C. E. 82/111 ;• 
 C. C. F. 2247.) 
 
 Acts of acknowledgment. 
 
 An acknowledgment by the debtor that he is liable for the 
 debt interrupts the prescription in his favour, and such an acknow- 
 ledgment may either be express or tacit. Such a tacit acknow- 
 ledgment of the debt is frequently found when the debtor pays 
 a sum on account of the debt or pays interest upon it. (C. C. F. 
 2248; B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 529; Guillourd, Pre- 
 scription, 1, n. 245; Planiol, 2, n. 665; C. A. Alex. 5 dec. 1889, 
 B. L. J. II, 59; DeHults, Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 102; Halton, 
 1, p. 209. See C. A. Alex. 18 mai 1911, B. L. J. XXIII, 330.) 
 
 Such an acknowledgment is a unilateral act, and is valid with- 
 out any acceptance. A fortiori its validity does not depend upon 
 the presence of the other party. (B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription,- 
 n. 83; Planiol, 1, n. 2713; C. A. Alex. 25 mai 1916, B. L. J. 
 XXVIII, 365.) This is true also in the Mohammedan law. 
 (C. A. Alex. 25 mai 1916, B. L. J. XXVIII, 366.) 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 553 
 
 Effects of interruption. 
 
 Interruption applies only to the past, it does not affect the 
 future. It does not hinder a new prescription from beginning 
 to run, and the new prescription will be of the same kind and 
 subject to the same rule as the old one. (B.-L. et Tissier, Pre- 
 scription, n. 551; Aubry et Hau, 5th ed. 2, p. 527.) 
 
 But there is one important exception to this rule. When the 
 prescription is of three hundred and sixty days for sums due to 
 tradesmen, and the tradesman has got a written acknowledgment 
 stating the amount of the debt, this not only interrupts the pre- 
 scription, but from this time the debt will be prescribed only by 
 fifteen years. This rule that the long prescription is here sub- 
 stituted is laid down in the French Code as to this short pre- 
 scription. (C. C. F. 2274; Cass. 7 mai 1906, D. 1908. 1. 65; 
 B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 755; Planiol, 2, n. 673.) 
 
 The reason of this short prescriptive period is that debts of 
 this kind are usually made without writing. If the parties make 
 them in writing, or if the creditor gets a written acknowledgment 
 of the debt, this shows sufficiently that the parties intended to 
 make their contract subject to the ordinary rule of fifteen 
 years' prescription. These reasons apply in the Egyptian law, 
 although the code is silent. (C. A. Alex. 9 mai 1894, B. L. J. 
 VI, 278; De Hults, Rep. vo. Prescription, n. 107.) 
 
 Suspension of prescription. 
 
 Prescription is suspended when the law says that owing to 
 certain special circumstances, or in order to protect certain classes 
 of persons, it is not to run during a certain time. The period 
 during which the suspension continues is not counted, but the 
 period before the suspension begins is counted, and so is that 
 which comes after the cause of suspension has been removed. 
 The suspension does not, like interruption, wipe out and annihilate 
 the benefit of a period which has passed. It applies only to the 
 present. It does not, like interruption, originate in the act of a 
 person by his bringing a claim or making an acknowledgment; 
 it is a favour given by the law for reasons of equity. And it is 
 given to certain persons precisely because they are not in a posi- 
 tion to interrupt prescription by themselves. It does not run 
 against minors until majority. (C. A. Alex. 3 juin 1909, 
 B. L. J. XXI, 373.) 
 
554 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 When one of the co-creditors in a joint and several debt is a 
 minor and prescription is suspended in his favour, this does not 
 benefit his co-creditors. (See supra, p. 406.) 
 
 Causes of suspension. 
 
 Prescriptions, the terms of which are more than five years, do 
 not run against persons subject to incapacity. (C. C. E. 85/114; 
 C. C. F. 2278; C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 1913, B. L. J. XXVI, 118.) 
 But, prescription against a lunatic is not suspended unless he 
 has been formally interdicted. Although a man is notoriously 
 a lunatic and resides in a lunatic asylum, prescription will run 
 against him if he has not been interdicted. The incapacity must 
 lie ime incapacity legalement constatee. (C. A. Alex. 22 mai 
 1902, B. L. J. XIV, 325.) This is in accordance with the 
 French law. The suspension is by the terms of the French Code 
 in favour of minors and interdits. (C. C. F. 2252, 2278. See 
 Cass. 31 dec. 1866, S. 67. 1. 153, Journal du Palais, 67, p. 366; 
 B.-L. et Tissier, Prescription, n. 423; Aubry et Rau, 5th ed. 
 2, p. 497.) The Egyptian law is the same. (C. A. Alex. 30 dec. 
 1916, B. L. J. XXVI, 118.) 
 
 May there be other causes of suspension? 
 
 According to the old French law the court was entitled to find 
 in any particular case that prescription was suspended against 
 a person by reason of special circumstances. If he was able to 
 prove that as a matter of fact it had not been possible for him to 
 claim his right, the court applied the rule contra nan valentem 
 agere non currit prazscriptio . 
 
 A man who could show that he had been absent from the 
 country, that he was ignorant of his right, and so on, was relieved 
 from the prescription which had run against him. 
 
 This led to abuses, and the French Code laid down a new rule: 
 Prescription runs against all persons unless they fall within an 
 exception established by laic. (C. C. F. 2251; BrissaucU 
 History of French Private Law, p. 364, note 8; B.-L. et Tissier, 
 Prescription, n. 367; Guillouard, Prescription, 1, n. 153.) 
 
 But the law did not provide for some cases in which equity was 
 strongly in favour of allowing suspension. If, for example, owing 
 to war, the courts were not sitting and an action could not be 
 brought, it would be very hard to hold that the plaintiff had lost 
 his right. The French jurisprudence, accordingly, has held that 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 555 
 
 C. C. F. 2251 does not apply to causes of suspension which do 
 not depend upon the capacity of the plaintiff. The rule applied 
 by the courts is la prescription ne court point \contre celui qui 
 est dans V ' impossibilite absolue d'agir, par suite d'un empechement 
 quelconque resultant de la loi, de la convention ou He la force 
 majeure. (Cass. 28 juin 1870, D. 70. 1. 309; Req. 2 mai 1900, 
 
 D. 1900. 1. 422.) 
 
 The jurisprudence is disapproved of by almost all the writers. 
 The courts apply the maxim contra non valentem agere non currit 
 prcescriptio as if it were adopted in the French Code, Avhereas the 
 codifiers intended by this article C. C. F. 2251, to limit the 
 application of this rule to the cases expressly specified in the code. 
 (Laurent, 32, n. 38; Planiol, 1, n. 2701; B.-L. et Tissier, Pre- 
 scription, n. 375.) MM. Aubry et Rau contend that prescription 
 is suspended only when there is a legal obstacle to the exercise of 
 the action. When the obstacle is merely one of fact, such as 
 imprisonment, difficulty of communication and the like, there is 
 no suspension of prescription in the true sense of the term. But 
 the judge has poAver to relieve the creditor from the effects of the 
 prescription which has run against him, if the creditor took his 
 action promptly when the obstacle was removed. (5th eel. 2, 
 p. 500. See C. A. Alex. 11 fevr. 1909, B. L. J. XXI, 189; 
 C. A. Alex. 27 avril 1899, B. L. J. XI, 211.) There is much 
 to be said from the legislative point of view for this opinion, 
 but it is impossible to find support for it in the French Code. (Cf . 
 German Code, arts. 203, 215.) 
 
 The Egyptian Code has no article like C. C. F. 2251, and!, 
 according to the Egyptian jurisprudence, a person who shows that 
 it was absolutely impossible for him to bring an action is relieved 
 from the prescription, and a suspension of this kind applies even 
 to the short prescription of five years. In one case the widow of 
 a soldier killed in the Sudan in 1883 had been kept a prisoner 
 in Khartum till 1898, when that town was retaken. It was held 
 that she was entitled to claim arrears of pension from 1883, and 
 could not be met by the plea of five ylears' prescription applicable 
 to such payments. 
 
 L'impossibilite absolue d'agir constitue un cas de suspension 
 de toute prescription. (C. A. Alex. 13 dec. 1900, B. L. J. 
 XIII, 53; C. A. Alex. 3 janv. 1895, B. L. J. VII, 72; C. A. 
 Alex. 9 dec. 1896, B. L. J. IX, 53; C. A. Alex. 27 avril 1899, 
 B. L. J. XI, 211; Halton, 1, p. 212; De Hults, Rep. vo. Pre- 
 scription, n. 63.) 
 
556 THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS. 
 
 Upon the point whether absence from the country suspends 
 prescription the decisions are not harmonious. It has been so 
 considered. (C. A. Alex. 13 avril 1882, 11. O. VII, p. 140.) 
 On the other hand, it has been held that acquisitive prescription 
 runs against a person .who had been declared an absentee by a 
 judgment of the Mehkema Sharia. (C. A. Caire, 13 dec. 1910, 
 0. B. XII, n. 35.) In the Mohammedan law absence suspends 
 prescription. (Kadri Pacha, St at ut Reel, art. 256; C. A. Alex. 
 25 mai 1882, K. O. VII, p. 166.) But the Egyptian Code gives' 
 the benefit of suspension of prescription to persons subject to 
 incapacity. (C. C. E. 85/114.) The Mohammedan law, like 
 the old French law, admits to this benefit any person who can 
 prove a good excuse for his inaction. (Statut Reel, art. 256; 
 C. A. Caire, 13 dec. 1910, 0. B. XII, n. 35.) 
 
 Other modes of extinction. 
 
 The seven modes of extinction of obligations which the Egyp- 
 tian codes enumerate have now been explained. 
 
 It has been mentioned elsewhere that these are the regular and 
 normal modes in which any obligation may be extinguished. A 
 word may be said about two other modes of extinction to which 
 the code does not here refer. 
 
 (1) Expiration of the time limited by the parties for its 
 
 duration. 
 
 An obligation entered into for a certain time naturally ter- 
 minates when that period expires. It has in fact then been paid, 
 and, therefore, it is hardly necessary to add this as a separate 
 mode of extinction of obligations, though this is done in some 
 codes. (C. C. Q. 1138.) For example, if I grant a lease for 
 ten years, at the end of the ten years the lease comes to an end 
 by efflux of time. 
 
 (2) Death of the creditor and debtor in certain cases. 
 
 The cases in which an obligation is extinguished by the death 
 of the creditor or of the debtor have been discussed under the head 
 of the representation of a party to a contract by his heirs and 
 successors. (Supra, p. 16.) 
 
 Some obligations are strictly personal both as to the creditor 
 and the debtor, such as a contract with a barber to shave one for 
 
EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. 557 
 
 a certain period, or, a contract with a sick-nurse for her services 
 during an illness. Others are (extinguished by the death of the 
 debtor, but survive the death of the creditor, such as the contract 
 with a clerk or domestic servant, while the majority of debts 
 transmit in favour of the heirs of the creditors and against tho 
 heirs of the debtor. (Pothier, Obligations, nos. 673 — -675.) 
 
 And in some of the special contracts the code contains a provi- 
 sion on the subject. 
 
 So, a civil partnership is dissolved by the death of one of the 
 partners, because in this contract one chooses a partner from con- 
 fidence in his integrity and ability, and one has not necessarily 
 the same reliance on his heir or representative. 
 
 But it may be stipulated that the heir of a deceased partner 
 shall step into his shoes. (C. C. E. 445/542; C. C. F. 1865.) 
 
 So also mandate terminates by the natural death of the mandator 
 or mandatary. (C. C. E. 529/650; C. C. F. 2003.) 
 
( 559 ) 
 
 CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED 
 WITH PAGES OF VOLUME II. 
 
 Egyptian Native Civil Code. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 23 290 
 
 30 202 
 
 46 34, 45 
 
 48 30 
 
 54 438 
 
 (35 142, 1G6 
 
 76 521 
 
 80 514, 540, 544, 547, 548 
 
 82 551, 552 
 
 85 554, 556 
 
 87 34, 45, 521 
 
 90 .- 362 
 
 91 2, 30 
 
 92 30, 31 
 
 94 189 
 
 96 363 
 
 97 372, 373 
 
 98 364, 381, 384, 385, 389 
 
 99 372, 376 
 
 100 372, 376 
 
 101 353 
 
 102 355, 356, 359 
 
 103 328, 330 
 
 104 339 
 
 105 345, 347, 369 
 
 106 345, 347 
 
 107 404, 405 
 
 108 407, 408, 409, 413, 429 
 
 109 408, 414 
 
 110 416, 417. 421, 442 
 
 111 416 
 
 112 417, 419 
 
 Art. page 
 
 113 419, 420 
 
 114 422, 428 
 
 115 414, 424, 429, 430 
 
 116 407, 431 
 
 117 219, 227, 230, 234 
 
 118 219, 232 
 
 119 206, 287, 290, 293 
 
 120 206, 215. 216 
 
 121 237, 250, 251, 252. 255 
 
 122 251. 257, 394 
 
 123 215, 250, 384, 393, 397 
 
 124 :216. 244. 245 
 
 125 394 
 
 126 248 
 
 127 244, 248 
 
 131 142, 166 
 
 137 12, 26. 53, 69 
 
 140 363 
 
 141 ...1, 12, 24, 26. 93. 94, 100, 
 
 549 
 
 142 12, 27 
 
 143 1, 87, 109, 122, 549 
 
 144 141, 142, 144, 153, 155, 
 
 156, 168, 177 
 
 145 166, 187, 213, 352 
 
 146 213 
 
 147 192, 194 
 
 148 187, 190. 191. 194 
 
 150 410, 411, 414 
 
 151 258 
 
 152 411 
 
 154 201 
 
560 
 
 CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 Egyptian Native Civil Code — continued. 
 
 Art. 
 
 15-5 
 
 156 
 
 157 
 
 158 
 
 159 
 
 160 
 
 161 
 
 162 
 
 163 
 
 164 
 
 165 
 
 166 
 
 167 
 
 168 
 
 169 
 170 
 171 
 172 
 173 
 174 
 175 
 176 
 177 
 178 
 179 
 180 
 182 
 183 
 185 
 186 
 187 
 187 
 188 
 189 
 189 
 190 
 191 
 192 
 193 
 194 
 195 
 196 
 
 
 201. 
 
 443, 
 
 
 
 
 9,9 
 
 444. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 446, 
 
 455, 
 
 462, 
 
 
 414, 
 
 166. 
 
 449. 
 
 350, 
 
 392, 
 452, 
 
 395, 
 
 467, 
 
 432, 
 503, 
 
 444, 
 
 414, 
 
 466, 
 
 
 471, 
 
 
 471, 
 
 316. 
 
 
 217. 
 355 
 
 287, 
 373, 
 
 374, 
 
 316 
 
 479, 
 
 423. 
 
 
 
 426, 
 
 428, 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 9,9, 
 
 483, 
 
 al. 2 ... 
 
 
 
 
 466, 
 
 
 al 2 
 
 
 488, 
 
 
 499. 
 
 
 351. 
 
 500, 
 
 506 
 
 
 507 
 
 
 PAGE 
 
 203 
 203 
 203 
 483 
 445 
 445 
 446 
 465 
 446 
 455 
 448 
 448 
 450 
 451, 
 515 
 452 
 452 
 454 
 469 
 468 
 474 
 471 
 475 
 476 
 476 
 482 
 497 
 428 
 499 
 497 
 482 
 490 
 492 
 488 
 489 
 490 
 492 
 491 
 499 
 515 
 510 
 508 
 513 
 
 Art. 
 
 197 
 
 198 
 
 199 
 
 200 
 
 201 
 
 202 
 
 203 
 
 204 
 
 205 
 
 206 
 
 207 
 
 208 
 
 209 
 
 210 
 
 211 
 
 212 
 
 213 
 
 215 
 
 218 
 
 219 
 
 220 
 
 222 
 
 232 
 
 241 
 
 261 
 
 264 
 
 265 
 
 266. 
 
 268 
 
 270 
 
 279 
 
 281 
 
 283 
 
 284 
 
 297 
 
 298 
 307 
 324 
 332 
 333 
 342 
 344 
 
 PAGE 
 
 511, 512, 514 
 
 502, 511, 514 
 
 513 
 
 502 
 
 420, 502 
 
 516 
 
 516, 518, 519 
 
 522, 524, 530, 547 
 
 523 
 
 540, 549 
 
 540, 550 
 
 123, 523 
 
 527, 534, 536, 537 
 
 527, 537, 538 
 
 414, 524, 526, 539 
 
 528 
 
 522, 528 
 
 146, 148. 192, 455 
 
 290 
 
 455, 497 
 
 455, 497 
 
 192 
 
 122 
 
 482 
 
 368 
 
 34, 388 
 
 388 
 
 .32, 217, 317, 349, 368, 481 
 
 368 
 
 41 
 
 222 
 
 356 
 
 454 
 
 454 
 
 32, 217, 317, 330, 349, 
 
 355, 481 
 
 482 
 
 257 
 
 542 
 
 .350, 392 
 
 290 
 
 142 
 
CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 561 
 
 Egyptian Native Civ 
 
 Art. 
 
 345 
 
 PAGE 
 
 348 
 
 349 
 
 357 
 
 458, 496, 513 
 
 30 
 
 366 
 
 55 
 
 370 183, 317 
 
 378 183 
 
 389 23 
 
 392 290 
 
 393 286 
 
 407 10 
 
 409 22, 410 
 
 411 19, 290, 302, 444 
 
 414 168 
 
 417 290 
 
 424 482 
 
 426 247 
 
 444 167 
 
 445 10; 557 
 
 470 214 
 
 482 353 
 
 488 167, 509 
 
 489 290, 304 
 
 499 410 
 
 500 360 
 
 il Code — continued. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 505 247, 463 
 
 509 419, 502 
 
 514 162 
 
 521 150 
 
 522 10 
 
 524 13, 52 
 
 526 213 
 
 527 14 
 
 529 10, 557 
 
 530 450 
 
 541 498 
 
 544 290 
 
 555 94 
 
 562 290, 360, 379 
 
 574 "379 
 
 575 462 
 
 607 338 
 
 608 44, 338, 346 
 
 611 20, 27, 37, 39, 346, 370 
 
 613 23 
 
 615 20, 133, 346 
 
 617 21, 40, 346 
 
 652 290 
 
 Egyptian Mixed Civil Code. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 42 290 
 
 51 202 
 
 68 34, 45 
 
 70 30 
 
 77 438 
 
 90 142, 166 
 
 102 • 521 
 
 108 514, 540, 544, 547, 548 
 
 111 551, 552 
 
 114 554, 556 
 
 116 34, 45, 521 
 
 144 362 
 
 145 2, 30 
 
 146 30, 31 
 
 148 189 
 
 W. — VOL. II. 
 
 Art. 
 
 150 
 
 151 372, 
 
 152 364, 381, 384, 385, 
 
 153 372, 
 
 154 372, 
 
 155 
 
 156 355, 356, 
 
 157 
 158 
 159 
 160 
 161 
 
 .328. 
 
 .34; 
 
 347, 
 345, 
 404, 
 
 162 407, 409, 413, 
 
 163 
 
 164 
 
 36 
 
 PAGE 
 
 363 
 
 373 
 389 
 376 
 376 
 353 
 359 
 330 
 339 
 369 
 347 
 405 
 429 
 408 
 408 
 
562 
 
 CONX'ORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 Egyptian Mixed Civ 
 
 Art. page 
 
 165 408 ! 
 
 166 416. 417. 421. 442 | 
 
 167 416 
 
 168 417. 419 
 
 169 419. 420 
 
 170 422. 428 
 
 171 424, 429, 430. 431 
 
 172 407 
 
 173 219. 227, 230, 234 
 
 174 234 
 
 175 232 
 
 176 219 
 
 177 206, 287, 290, 293 
 
 178 206, 215 
 
 179 237, 250, 251, 252, 255 
 
 180 251, 257, 394 
 
 181 215, 250, 384, 393, 397 
 
 182 216, 244 
 
 185 394 
 
 186 248 
 
 187 244, 248 
 
 191 142, 166 
 
 197 117, 136 
 
 198 ....? 12, 26, 53, 69 
 
 201 363 
 
 202 ...1, 12, 24, 26, 93, 94, 97, 
 
 100, 549 
 
 203 12, 27 
 
 204 ...1, 87, 105, 109, 122. 549 
 
 205 141, 142, 144, 153, 155, 
 
 156, 168, 177, 187 
 
 206 166, 213, 352 
 
 207 213 
 
 208 192, 194 
 
 209 187, 190 
 
 211 410, 411 
 
 212 258 
 
 214 411 
 
 216 201 
 
 217 203 
 
 218 203 
 
 219 201. 203 
 
 220 203 
 
 il Code — continued. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 221 443, 483 
 
 222 445 
 
 223 29, 444. 445 
 
 224 446 
 
 225 446, 455, 460, 462, 465 
 
 226 446 
 
 227 455, 456, 459 
 
 228 448 
 
 229 166. 448 
 
 230 449. 450 
 
 231 350, 392, 395, 432, 451, 
 
 452, 467, 503, 515 
 
 232 452 
 
 233 444 
 
 234 454 
 
 235 466, 469 
 
 236 468 
 
 237 471, 474 
 
 238 471 
 
 239 471, 475 
 
 240 316, 476 
 
 241 217, 287, 374, 476 
 
 242 316, 355, 373, 479, 482 
 
 243 497 
 
 245 423, 428 
 
 246 426, 428, 499 
 
 248 497 
 
 249 482 
 
 251 29, 483, 485, 490 
 
 251 ol. 2 492, 496 
 
 252 466, 488 
 
 253 489, 490 
 
 254 492 
 
 255 488. 491 
 
 256 499 
 
 257 499, 515 
 
 258 351, 500, 506, 510 
 
 259 507, 508 
 
 260 511 
 
 261 511, 512, 514 
 
 262 502, 511, 514 
 
 263 513 
 
 264 502 
 
CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 56:) 
 
 Egyptian Mixed Civil Code — continued. 
 
 Art. 
 
 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Art. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 265 
 
 
 
 .420. 502 
 
 436 
 
 496, 513 
 
 266 
 
 
 
 516 
 
 449 
 
 55 
 
 267 
 
 
 516, 
 
 518, 519 
 
 453 
 
 183 
 
 268 
 
 522, 
 
 524, 
 
 530, 547 
 
 454 
 
 317 
 
 269 
 
 
 
 523 
 
 455 
 
 317 
 
 270 
 
 
 
 .540, 549 
 
 463 
 
 183 
 
 271 
 
 
 
 .540, 550 
 
 474 
 
 23 
 
 272 
 
 
 
 .123, 523 
 
 479 
 
 290 
 
 273 
 
 527, 
 
 534, 
 
 536, 537 
 
 480 
 
 286 
 
 274 
 
 
 527, 
 594 
 
 537, 538 
 526, 539 
 
 495 
 
 10 
 
 275 
 
 500 
 
 22, 410 
 
 276 
 
 
 
 528 
 
 502 
 
 ....19, 290, 302, 444 
 
 277 
 
 
 
 .522, 528 
 
 506 
 
 168 
 
 280 
 
 
 146 
 
 148, 455 
 
 509 
 
 290 
 
 283 
 
 
 
 290 
 
 516 
 
 482 
 
 284 
 
 
 
 .455, 497 
 
 518 
 
 247 
 
 285 
 
 
 
 .455, 497 
 
 541 
 
 167 
 
 297 
 
 
 
 122 
 
 542 
 
 10, 557 
 
 307 
 
 
 
 482 
 
 572 
 
 214 
 
 328 
 
 
 
 368 
 
 590 
 
 353 
 
 333 
 
 
 
 ...34, 388 
 
 596 
 
 167, 509 
 
 334 
 
 
 
 388 
 
 597 
 
 509 
 
 336.. 
 
 .32, 217, 317 
 
 349, 
 
 368, 481 
 
 598 
 
 290, 304 
 
 338 
 
 
 
 368 
 
 609 
 
 410 
 
 341 
 
 
 
 41 
 
 610 
 
 360 
 
 350 
 
 
 
 222 
 
 617 
 
 247, 463 
 
 353 
 
 
 
 356 
 
 622 
 
 419, 502 
 
 355 
 
 
 
 454 
 
 628 
 
 162 
 
 356 
 
 
 
 454 
 
 638 
 
 150 
 
 371 
 
 32, 217, 
 
 317, 
 
 330, 349, 
 
 640 
 
 10 
 
 
 
 
 355, 481 
 
 643 
 
 13, 52 
 
 373 
 
 
 
 482 
 
 646 
 
 213 
 
 380 
 
 
 
 192 
 
 648 
 
 14 
 
 381 
 
 
 
 257 
 
 650 
 
 10, 557 
 
 387 
 
 
 
 192 
 
 651 
 
 450 
 
 402 
 
 
 
 542 
 
 663 
 
 498 
 
 413 
 
 
 
 88 
 
 666 
 
 679 
 
 290 
 
 415 
 
 
 
 350, 392 
 290 
 
 ." 94 
 
 49,7 
 
 686 
 
 290, 360, 379 
 
 430 
 
 
 
 142 
 
 697 
 
 379 
 
 431 
 
 
 
 348 
 
 698 
 
 462 
 
 435 
 
 
 
 458 
 
 733 
 
 338 
 
 36 (2) 
 
564 
 
 CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 Egyptian Mixed Civil Code — continued. 
 
 Art. page Art. page 
 
 7:54 44. 338, 346 742 20. 133. 346 
 
 737 20. 27. 37. 39, 346, 370 744 21. 40. 346 
 
 740 23 
 
 Egyptian" Native Code of Civil and Commercial Procedure. 
 
 Art. 
 
 291 
 
 294 
 
 368 
 
 369 
 
 384 
 
 410 
 
 434 
 
 .95. 
 
 Art. 
 
 126 
 
 668 
 
 500 
 
 674 
 
 529 
 
 685 
 
 529 
 
 695 
 
 208 
 
 697 
 
 451 
 
 698 
 
 510 
 
 699 
 
 .471. 
 
 95 
 
 95 
 
 474 
 
 474 
 
 474 
 
 472 
 
 .471. 472 
 
 Egyptian Mixed Code of Civil and Commercial Procedure. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 332 126 
 
 335 500 
 
 412 529 
 
 413 529 
 
 437 208 
 
 471 95, 184. 451 
 
 496 -. 510 
 
 675 462 
 
 Art. page 
 
 760 95 
 
 764 95 
 
 773 471, 474 
 
 783 474 
 
 785 474 
 
 786 472 
 
 787 471. 472 
 
 Egyptian Native Commercial Code. 
 
 Art. 
 
 2 
 
 22 
 
 48 
 
 82 
 
 92 
 
 97 268. 288 
 
 101 276 
 
 109 409 
 
 119 379 
 
 125 379 
 
 PAGE 
 
 409 
 411 
 
 28 
 
 14 
 
 263 
 
 Art. 
 
 137 
 
 148 
 
 162 
 
 180 
 
 194 
 
 195 
 
 221 
 
 228 
 
 :m 
 
 .356. 
 
 PAGE 
 411 
 
 105 
 210 
 248 
 487 
 357 
 357 
 107 
 16 
 
CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 Egyptian Mixed Commercial Code. 
 
 565 
 
 Art. 
 
 2 ; 
 
 28 
 
 54 
 
 86 
 
 97 
 
 102 268, 288 
 
 106 276 
 
 114 409 
 
 144 411 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Art. 
 
 409 
 
 169 
 
 411 
 
 187 
 
 28 
 
 201 
 
 14 
 
 202 
 
 26:3 
 
 PAGE 
 210 
 
 248 
 
 487 
 
 357 
 
 229 356, 357 
 
 235 107, 110 
 
 236 107 
 
 338 16 
 
 French Civil Code. 
 
 Art. 
 
 6 
 
 187 
 
 191 
 
 548 
 
 •">•"> ."> 
 
 617 
 
 705 
 
 725 
 
 727 
 
 72!) 
 
 7S3 
 
 802 
 
 870 
 
 873 
 
 878 
 
 896 
 
 900 
 
 906 
 
 9:38 :....30, 31 
 
 957 70 
 
 1048 84 
 
 1071 41 
 
 1088 188 
 
 1101 362 
 
 1119 12, 46, 49, 51, 387 
 
 1120 12, 46 
 
 1121 12, 46, 53, 64, 69 
 
 1122 16 
 
 1126 442 
 
 1131 189 
 
 .56 
 
 PAGE 
 
 7 
 . 101 
 , 101 
 . 170 
 . 166 
 . 517 
 . 517 
 . 84 
 . 518 
 . 518 
 . 518 
 . 518 
 . 4:38 
 . 518 
 . 438 
 . 84 
 . 332 
 84 
 
 Art. 
 
 1134 
 
 1138. 
 
 1139 
 
 1141 
 
 1142 
 
 1143 
 
 1144 
 
 1145 
 
 1146 
 
 1147 
 
 1148 
 
 1149 
 
 1150 
 
 1151 
 
 1152 
 
 1153 
 
 1154 
 
 1157 
 
 1162 
 
 1165 
 
 1166 
 
 1167 
 
 1168 
 
 1171 
 
 1172 
 
 1173 
 
 1174 
 
 1175 
 
 1176 
 
 1177 
 
 PAGE 
 
 1, 2, 9 
 
 .30, 32, 317, 355, 368, 480 
 
 208 
 
 45 
 
 220, 225 
 
 230 
 
 220 
 
 211 
 
 206, 211, 392 
 
 206, 288, 292, 293 
 
 288 
 
 250, 252 
 
 257, 394 
 
 255, 394 
 
 215, 393, 397 
 
 ....244, 245, 246, 247, 250 
 
 248 
 
 50 
 
 363 
 
 1, 9, 12, 26, 66, 67 
 
 92, 94, 100 
 
 1, 87, 92, 105, 121 
 
 328, 330 
 
 334 
 
 331 
 
 331 
 
 262, 332 
 
 3:35 
 
 339 341 
 
 339, 341 
 
566 
 
 CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODE6 CITED. 
 
 French Civil Code — continued. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 1 178 341, 343 
 
 1179 336, 346, 347, 369 
 
 1180 97, 336 
 
 1182 347, 349 
 
 1184 10, 219, 221 
 
 1185 335, 350 
 
 1186 336, 351, 352 
 
 1187 353 
 
 1188 355, 356, 359 
 
 1189 362 
 
 1190 363 
 
 1191 362 
 
 1192 370 
 
 1193 372, 373 
 
 1194 372, 376 
 
 1195 372 
 
 1196 372 
 
 1197 404 
 
 1198 404, 406 
 
 1199 • 406, 416 
 
 1200 407, 408 
 
 1201 408 
 
 1202 409 
 
 1203 414 
 
 1205 416 
 
 1206 416, 442 
 
 1207 417 
 
 1208 417, 418 
 
 1209 419 
 
 1210 427 
 
 1211 423, 424 
 
 1212 424 
 
 1214 424 
 
 1215 426 
 
 1216 407, 430 
 
 1217 431 
 
 1219 442 
 
 1220 432, 433, 518 
 
 1221 433, 435, 436, 437 
 
 1224 439 
 
 1225 431, 439, 440, 441 
 
 1226 382, 386 
 
 1227 387, 388 
 
 Art. page 
 
 1228 389' 
 
 1229 389, 399, 400 
 
 1230 381, 391 
 
 1231 395 
 
 1232 ...402, 441 
 
 1233 402, 441 
 
 1234 443, 483- 
 
 1235 445 
 
 1236 29, 446 
 
 1238 195, 448 
 
 1240 450 
 
 1241 449 
 
 1242 451 
 
 1243 451, 503 
 
 1244 350, 392, 395, 452, 515 
 
 1247 452 
 
 1249 457 
 
 1250 457, 458 
 
 1251 457, 458 
 
 1252 463. 
 
 1254 468 
 
 1255 468 
 
 1256 469 
 
 1257 472 
 
 1258 473 
 
 1264 473 
 
 1272 485 
 
 1273 486 
 
 1274 29, 485 
 
 1275 484, 493 
 
 1276 495 
 
 1277 495 
 
 1278 488, 490 
 
 1279 490- 
 
 1280 490, 492 
 
 1281 488, 492. 
 
 1282 455, 498 
 
 1283 455. 498 
 
 1284 498 
 
 1285 428 
 
 1286 498 
 
 1289 499 
 
 1290 499. 515. 
 
CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 567 
 
 French Civil Code — c 
 
 Art. 
 1291 
 1293 
 1294 
 1295 
 1296 
 1297 
 1298 
 1299 
 1300 
 1301 
 1302 
 
 1302 
 1312 
 1321 
 
 1328 
 1348 
 1351 
 1370 
 1371 
 1372 
 1373 
 1374 
 1375 
 1376 
 1377 
 1378 
 1381 
 1388 
 1395 
 1583 
 1585 
 1589 
 1599 
 1608 
 1612 
 1624 
 1633 
 1654 
 1673 
 1689 
 1690 
 
 PAGE 
 
 351, 500, 503 
 
 507, 508, 509 
 
 420, 502, 503 
 
 511, 513, 514 
 
 506 
 
 511 
 
 513 
 
 511, 514 
 
 516 
 
 516, 519 
 
 ....195, 213, 217, 299, 316, 
 317, 476, 478 
 
 al. 2 286 
 
 166 
 
 130, 131, 132, 133, 135, 
 
 136 
 
 27 
 
 146, 192 
 
 122 
 
 144, 201, 202 
 
 140, 144 
 
 148, 150, 152, 157, 177 
 
 148, 153 
 
 148, 154 
 
 148, 156 
 
 166, 187 
 
 190 
 
 195, 213 
 
 187 
 
 196 
 
 9 
 
 30, 31 
 
 482 
 
 228 
 
 34, 388 
 
 454 
 
 222 
 
 217 
 
 257 
 
 348 
 
 458 
 
 46 
 
 ontinued. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 1703 31 
 
 1717 55 
 
 1722 317 
 
 1733 300, 301 
 
 1743 23 
 
 1772 286 
 
 1780 394, 397 
 
 1782 304 
 
 1792 22 
 
 1794 10 
 
 1795 19, 302 
 
 1798 168 
 
 1825 286 
 
 1846 247 
 
 1864 167 
 
 1865 10, 557 
 
 1881 214 
 
 1887 411 
 
 1889 11 
 
 1944 353 
 
 1947 509 
 
 1948 167, 509 
 
 1953 304 
 
 1961 al. 3 475 
 
 1991 153 
 
 1992 150 
 
 1996 213 
 
 1997 13, 52 
 
 1998 14 
 
 2002 411 
 
 2003 10, 557 
 
 2005 450 
 
 2007 10 
 
 2020 360 
 
 2028 247 
 
 2035 519 
 
 2036 418 
 
 2093 24, 94 
 
 2125 135, 338 
 
 2131 360, 379 
 
 2168 379 
 
 2219 521, 522, 524 
 
 2220 540, 544 
 
568 
 
 CONCORDANCE OF ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 French Civil Code — continued. 
 
 Art. page 
 
 2221 544, 547 
 
 2222 548 
 
 2223 5,30 
 
 2224 529 
 
 2225 549, 550 
 
 2246 551 
 
 2247 552 
 
 2248 552 
 
 2249 417, 442 
 
 2251 554, 555 
 
 2252 554 
 
 2257 532 
 
 PAGE 
 
 531 
 
 . 531 
 . 527 
 
 Art. 
 
 2260 
 
 2261 
 
 2271 
 
 2272 527, 535 
 
 2273 537 
 
 2274 553 
 
 2275 528 
 
 2277 524 
 
 2278 554 
 
 2279 34, 44 
 
 2280 34, 45 
 
 2281 521 
 
 Quebec Civil Code. 
 
 13 
 
 17 
 
 155 
 
 156 
 
 765 
 
 795 
 
 838 
 
 983 
 
 1019 
 
 1022 
 
 1023 
 
 1025 
 
 1027 
 
 1028 
 
 1029 
 
 1030 
 
 1031 
 
 1032 
 
 1033 
 
 1036 
 
 1039 
 
 1040 
 
 1041 
 
 1042 
 
 1043 
 
 1044 
 
 1045 
 
 n. 24 
 
 / 
 
 289 
 
 101 
 
 101 
 
 56 
 
 30 
 
 56 
 
 142 
 
 363 
 
 1, 2 
 
 12 
 
 31 
 
 37, 45 
 
 12, 26, 47 
 
 ..12, 53, 64, 66, 69 
 
 16 
 
 93, 97, 100 
 
 106 
 
 122 
 
 110, 121 
 
 106 
 
 1, 123 
 
 144 
 
 158 
 
 .140, 148, 152, 157 
 
 153 
 
 154 
 
 1046 
 1047 
 1048 
 1049 
 1050 
 1052 
 1057 
 
 148 
 187 
 191 
 195 
 289 
 187 
 201 
 
 1065 10, 220 
 
 1066 220 
 
 1067 206 
 
 1069 218 
 
 1070 206 
 
 1071 
 1072 
 1076 
 1079 
 1085 
 1091 
 1092 
 1093 
 1094 
 1095 
 1103 
 1105 
 1106 
 1114 
 1119 
 
 293 
 
 289 
 
 215 
 
 318 
 
 346 
 
 353 
 
 .355, 356 
 
 362 
 
 363 
 
 370 
 
 407 
 
 410 
 
 410 
 
 427 
 
 ...... 426 
 
CONCORDANCE OV ARTICLES OF CODES CITED. 
 
 i69 
 
 Art. page 
 
 1120 407 
 
 1122 432, 433 
 
 1123 433 
 
 1125 442 
 
 1130 439, 441 
 
 1131 382 
 
 1132 388 
 
 1135 396 
 
 1138 443, 556 
 
 Quebec Civil Code — continued. 
 Art. 
 
 1141 
 1143 
 1157 
 1161 
 1170 
 1172 
 1174 
 1176 
 1178 
 1179 
 1180 
 1183 
 1190 
 1191 
 1193 
 1196 
 1197 
 
 29 
 195 
 463 
 469 
 485 
 
 29 
 495 
 488 
 492 
 492 
 488 
 498 
 507 
 420 
 506 
 511 
 511 
 
 1198 516, 518 
 
 1199 516 
 
 1200 213, 217, 478 
 
 1202 480 
 
 1212 130, 131 
 
 1225 27 
 
 1241 122 
 
 1260 9 
 
 1472 30 
 
 1476 
 
 1487 
 
 1495 
 
 1570 
 
 1571 
 
 1596 
 
 1604 
 
 1638 
 
 1650 
 
 1663 
 
 1688 
 
 1691 
 
 1692 
 
 1709 
 
 1716 
 
 1717 
 
 1720 
 
 1755 
 
 1759 
 
 1767 
 
 1768 
 
 1774 
 
 1810 
 
 1812 
 
 1815 
 
 1895 
 
 1981 24, 94 
 
 2038 135, 338 
 
 2085 41 
 
 2098 21, 27, 39, 40, 41, 133 
 
 2184 544 
 
 2268 44, 45 
 
 2359 31 
 
 2362 31 
 
 PAGE 
 
 , 228 
 . 34 
 . 454 
 . 458 
 . 46 
 . 30 
 . 289 
 . 53 
 . 289 
 . 23 
 . 22 
 . 10 
 . 19 
 . 153 
 . 14 
 . 13 
 . 14 
 . 10 
 . 10 
 . 289 
 . 289 
 . 11 
 . 353 
 . 509 
 . 289 
 . 10 
 
( 571 ) 
 
 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 ABSENTEE, 
 
 is prescription suspended against... Vol. II., 556. 
 
 ACCEPTANCE. See Contract. 
 
 ACCESSOEY OBLIGATIONS. ..Vol. I., 43, 100. 
 may survive principal obligation... Vol. I., 101. 
 See Penal Clause, Obligations with a. 
 
 ACQUIESCENCE. See Modification of Contract by Parties. 
 
 ACT, 
 
 obligation resulting from an. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., 
 Chapter VII. 
 
 '"ACT OF GOD "...Vol. II., 326. 
 ACTES BEGUISES. See Simulation. 
 
 ACTIO BE IN REM VERSO. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., 
 
 Chapter VIII. 
 against occupant of immoveable without lease... Vol. II., 169, 
 
 170. 
 benefit created not enough to give action. ..Vol. II., 164. 
 building on another's land... Vol. II., 166. 
 conditions of... Vol. II., .179 seq. 
 for payment of tilings requisitioned by enemy forces... Vol. 
 
 II., 171. 
 for payment to incapable person. ..Vol. II., 166. 
 for value added to property of defendant... Vol. II., 170. 
 genealogist, claim by... Vol. II., 170. 
 general average losses fall under... Vol. II., 172. 
 gestion d'affaires, action on, distinguished... Vol. II.. 175. 
 name, origin of. ..Vol. II., 168. 
 
 partner, contract by, in his own name. ..Vol. II., 167. 
 partner, secret, claim against... Vol. II., 174. 
 payment of another's debt... Vol. II., 446. 
 various theories of. ..Vol. II., 175 seq. 
 
 See English Law; German Law: Swiss Law. 
 
 ADVOCATES, 
 
 prescription of sums due to... Vol. II., 536 seq. 
 
 AGENCE BE RENSEIGXEMENTS... Vol. II.. 282. 
 
572 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 AGENT. See Mandate. 
 
 ALEATORY CONTRACT. See Contract; Gaming Contract. 
 
 ALIMENT. See Gestlon d'affaires. 
 
 ALIMENTARY PROVISIONS. ..Vol. II., 201. 
 as natural obligations... Vol. I., 26. 
 renunciation of, invalid... Vol. I., 156. 
 
 rules as to persons bound to furnish, and as to persons en- 
 titled to claim. ..Vol. II., 203. 
 See English Law. 
 
 ALIMONY. See Alimentary Provisions. 
 
 ALTERNATIVE OBLIGATION. ..Vol. II., 362. 
 See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XIX. 
 choice, does it ever pass over to party not originally entitled 
 
 to it... Vol. II., 365. 
 choice, has it retroactive effect... Vol. II., 368. 
 how declared... Vol. II., 366. 
 right to make... Vol. II., 366. 
 when can Court make. ..Vol. II., 364. 
 when can debtor make... Vol. II., 363. 
 distinguished from conjunctive or facultative... Vol. II., 363. 
 impossibility, supervening, of performing one alternative... 
 
 Vol. II., 371 seq. 
 no alternative if one of things promised is unlawful or im- 
 possible ab Initio.. .Vol. II., 370. 
 obligation with penal clause is a special kind of... Vol. II., 
 364, 384. 
 
 See German Law. 
 
 AMERICAN LAW, 
 
 relativity of contract, in. ..Vol. II., 91. 
 
 stipulation of non-liability by shipowner... Vol. II., 284. 
 
 ANTICHRESIS, 
 
 creditor has not a privilege... Vol. II., 461. 
 
 APPORT. See Partnership. 
 
 APPROPRIATION OF PAYMENTS. See Imputation of Pay- 
 ments. 
 
 ARBITRATION. See Compromise. 
 
 ARCHITECT AND CONTRACTOR, 
 
 joint and several liability of... Vol. II., 410. 
 
 liabilitv of, may, by agreement, be for more than ten years 
 
 ...Vol. II., 542. 
 warranty of, passes to sub-purchaser... Vol. II., 22. 
 
 ARMY, 
 
 contract not to serve in. ..Vol. I., 150. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 573 
 
 AETIST. See Painter. 
 
 ASSIGNMENT OF CLAIM, 
 
 differs from subrogation... Vol. II., 458. 
 
 distinguished from novation... Vol. II., 495. 
 
 its effect on right to plead compensation... Vol. II.. 512. 
 
 ASSOCIATIONS, 
 
 are they persons... Vol. I., 342. 
 
 ASSOCIATION EN PARTICIPATION. See Partnership. 
 
 ASSURANCE. See Insurance. 
 
 ASSURANCE COLLECTIVE. See Stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 ASTREINTES, 
 
 Court, can it modify... Vol. II., 240, 242. 
 Court, when it may compel performance by... Vol. II.. 234. 
 fait personnel, may be enforced by... Vol. II., 239. 
 whether from date of first judgment or that of judgment in 
 appeal... Vol. II., 239. 
 
 See English Law; German Law. 
 
 AUTHOR, 
 
 nature of contract of, with publisher... Vol. I., 384. 
 
 AV ARIES COMMUNES. ..Vol. II., 172. 
 
 See Actio in de rem verso; General Average. 
 
 AY ANTS CAUSE. ..Vol. II., 17. 19. 
 
 BANKRUPTCY, 
 
 compensation, its effect on... Vol. II., 513. 
 
 term, debt subject to a, becomes instantly exigible... Vol. II., 
 
 355. 
 non-trader cannot be bankrupt... Vol. II., 107. 
 
 BEARER, 
 
 instruments payable to. See Commercial Law. 
 
 BET, 
 
 money paid cannot be repeated... Vol. I., 31, 177. 
 See Gaming Contract. 
 
 BILATERAL CONTRACT, 
 
 impossibility of performance, effect of. ..Vol. II.. 316. 333. 
 
 476. 
 nature of... Vol. I., 83. 
 resolutory condition implied in. ..Vol. I., 88. 
 
 BILL OF EXCHANGE, 
 
 acceptor who pays has not in general any recourse... \ ol. II., 
 430. 
 
574 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 BILL OF EXCHANGE— continued. 
 
 accommodation... Vol. I., 50. 
 giving bill does not novate debt. ..Vol. II., 487. 
 protest for non-acceptance creates facultative obligation... Vol. 
 II., 379. 
 
 BOl'LE DE XEIGE, 
 
 contract of... Vol. I., 50. 
 
 BREACH OF CONTRACT, 
 
 Court not bound to grant rescission for... Vol. II., 222. 
 plaintiff may keep part performance and claim damages... 
 
 Vol. "II., 224. 
 remedies for. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XII. 
 right of rescission for... Vol. II., 221 seq. 
 ■when judgment is equivalent to performance... Vol. II., 227. 
 See Specific Performance; Substituted Performance. 
 
 BREACH OF PROMISE OF MARRIAGE, 
 damages for... Vol. II., 253. 
 See Marriage. 
 
 BROTHEL, 
 
 contracts for lease of. ..Vol. I.. 115, 180. 
 
 BUILDER. See Architect. 
 
 BUILDINGS, 
 
 erected on land of another... Vol. II., 166. 
 
 CAPACITY. See Table of Contents, Vol. I.. Chapter XVII. 
 .ivil death abolished... Vol. I., 352. 
 incapable person cannot keep unjust enrichment... Vol. I., 355. 
 
 contract by. ..Vol. I., 212. 
 of moral persons... Vol. I., 342. 
 
 CARRIER, 
 
 acceptance of ticket, effect of. ..Vol. I., 196. 
 
 bound to carry at fixed prices... Vol. I., 164. 
 
 change of order given to... Vol. II., 10. 
 
 liability for damages which might have been foreseen... Vol. 
 
 II., 258. 
 owes dutv to persons in vehicles Avithout tickets... Vol. II., 
 
 266. 
 presumption of fault in case of theft. ..Vol. II., 304. 
 shipowner may exonerate himself from liability for fault of 
 
 captain and crew. ..Vol. II., 263. 
 war as excuse for non-performance of contract... Vol. II., 307. 
 
 See English Law; Exoneration from Liability, Stipula- 
 tions of; Forwarding Agent. 
 
 €AS FORTVIT. * 
 
 explained... Vol. II., 288. 
 See Fortuitous Event. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 575 
 
 CAUSE, 
 
 compared with motive and object... Vol. I., 104. 
 
 See Unlawful Contracts, 
 continuing... Vol. I., 49. 
 effects of illegality of... Vol. I., 175. 
 failure of, in bilateral contracts... Vol. I., 48. 
 false, meaning of. ..Vol. I., 52. 
 in bilateral contracts... Vol. I., 60. 
 partial want of. ..Vol. I., 51. 
 presumption of lawful... Vol. I., 48. 
 simulate... Vol. I., 53. 
 theory of. ..Vol. I., 55. 
 unlawful... Vol. I., 45. 
 
 See Unlawful Contracts, 
 want of. ..Vol. I., 50. 
 
 € AVE AT EMPTOR...Vo\. I., 272. 
 
 CERT AT BE DAMNO EVITANBO.. .Vol. II., 21, 114, 119. 
 
 CERTAT BE LUCRO CAPTANBO...Vo\. II., 114, 119. 
 
 CESSION BES CREANCES. See Assignment of Claims. 
 
 CHARITABLE FOUNDATIONS, 
 
 by gift subject to charge... Vol. II., 84. 
 
 effected by stipulations pour autrui... Vol. II., 56. 
 
 modification of.. .Vol. II., 3. 
 
 CHIROGRAPHIC OBLIGATIONS... Vol. I., 42. 
 See Creditors. 
 
 CHOSE JUGEE, 
 
 when defence of, is available to joint and several debtor... Vol. 
 II., 420. 
 
 CIVIL DEATH. See Capacity. 
 
 CLAQUE, 
 
 contract of... Vol. I., 122. 
 
 CLUB, 
 
 appeal from rules of. ..Vol. I., 147. 
 nature of contract by member. ..Vol. II., 8. 
 
 CODES, EGYPTIAN, 
 
 Arabic version of. ..Vol. I., 316. 
 
 COFERE-EORT. See Strong-box. 
 
 COMBINATIONS, 
 
 of traders, illegal... Vol. I., 171. 
 
 COMMERCIAL LAW, 
 
 bankruptcy confined to traders... Vol. II., 107. 
 putting in default, in... Vol. II., 207. 
 
576 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 COMMERCIAL LAW— <xm1mued. 
 
 rule possession vaut litre applies to negotiable instruments to 
 
 bearer... Vol. II., 44. 
 when is joint and several liability presumed... Vol. II., 409. 
 
 See Bill of Exchange; Carrier; Concordat ; Default, putting 
 in: Factors and Brokers. 
 
 COMMISSION NAIRE BE TRANSPORT. See Forwarding 
 
 Agent. 
 
 COMMISSION N AIRES. See Factors and Brokers. 
 
 COMPANY. See English Law; Persons. 
 
 COMPENSATION, 
 
 assignment, signification of, when it prevents... Vol. II., 512. 
 barred by arrestment or bankruptcy... Vol. II., 513. 
 cannot be pleaded if one of debts is subject to a term in favour 
 
 of debtor... Vol. II., 504. 
 Court, can it declare, ex officio... Vol. II., 500. 
 debts must be payable in same place... Vol. II., 506. 
 debts subject to... Vol. II., 501 seq. 
 facultative, when it takes place. ..Vol. II., 515. 
 imputation, rules of, apply to. ..Vol. II., 511. 
 in case of demcnnde reconventionnelle . . . Vol. II., 500. 
 joint and several debtor, how far he may plead. ..Vol. II., 419. 
 "liquid" debt, meaning of. ..Vol. II., 505 seq. 
 natural debt cannot be compensated with civil debt... Vol. II.. 
 
 504. 
 nature of... Vol. II., 499. 
 of debt subject to a term when debtor becomes bankrupt 
 
 or insolvent... Vol. II., 358. 
 plea of, may be renounced beforehand... Vol. II., 514. 
 plea of, may be taken on appeal... Vol. II.. 501. 
 specific things, no compensation between... Vol. II.. 503. 
 surety may plead... Vol. II., 502. 
 
 unseizable debt, no compensation with. ..Vol. II., 510. 
 when excluded... Vol. II.. 507. 
 
 See Deposit; English Law; Joint Obligations and Joint 
 and Several Obligations; Swiss Law. 
 
 COMPOUND INTEREST, 
 
 conditions under which it is allowed... Vol. II.. 248. 
 
 COMPROMISE, 
 
 clause of... Vol. I., 145. 
 
 mistake of law in. ..Vol. I., 255. 
 
 sale of land after compromise... Vol. II., 19. 
 
 strictly interpreted... Vol. I., 397. 
 
 CONSENSUAL CONTRACTS. ..Vol. I.. 101. 103. 
 
 CONCORDAT, 
 
 binds all creditors... Vol. II., 16. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 577 
 
 CONCUBINE, 
 
 payments to, not recoverable. ..Vol. I., 180. 
 promise fco make compensation to... Vol. I., 115. 
 promise to pay, when unlawful... Vol. I., 34, 114. 
 
 CONDICTIO CAUSA DATA CAUSA NON 8ECVT A.. .Vol. II.. 
 
 188. 
 
 CONDICTIO 
 
 ob tiirpem causam... Vol. I., 59. 
 sine causa... Vol. I., 58. 
 
 CONDITION, 
 
 definition of... Vol. II., 328. 
 
 fulfilment and failure of. ..Vol. II., 338. 
 
 fulfilment fraudulently pre vented... Vol. I., 359; Vol. II.. 
 
 341. 
 fulfilment, if no time fixed for, can Court fix a time... Vol. II.. 
 
 340. 
 fulfilment of, has it retroactive effect... Vol. II., 345 seq. 
 implied... Vol. II., 335. 
 in gifts and legacies when held pro non scripta...Wo\. II.. 
 
 332. 
 in restraint of marriage. See Marriage, 
 is strictly interpreted... Vol. II., 339. 
 nature of event on which obligation must depend... Vol. II., 
 
 329 seq. 
 potestative, must not be... Vol. II., 332 seq. 
 resolutory, express... Vol. I., 90. 
 resolutory, tacit... Vol. I., 88; Vol. II., 221. 
 suspensive and resolutive... Vol. II., 329. 
 
 See English Law; German Law; Swiss Law. 
 
 CONDITIONAL OBLIGATIONS. See Table of Contents, Vol. 
 
 II., Chapter XVII. 
 creditor has certain rights. ..Vol. II., 336 seq. 
 prescription of. ..Vol. II., 532. 
 risk in... Vol. II., 348. 
 
 See Condition. 
 
 CONFIRMATION. See Contract. 
 
 CONFUSION, 
 
 acceptance of succession with benefit of inventory prevents... 
 
 Vol. II., 518. 
 accessory .obligations, when discharged by... Vol. II., 518. 
 does not take place in Mohammedan law of succession... Vol. 
 
 II., 517. 
 in case of joint and several debtors... Vol. II., 419. 
 in case of joint and several debtors extinguishes share of one 
 
 co-debtor only... Vol. II., 519. 
 
 CONSENT. See Contract; Duress; Fraud; Interpretation jof 
 Contracts ; Mistake ; Simul ation . 
 w. — vol. ii. 37 
 
578 [NDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 CONSERVATORY ACTS, 
 
 conditional creditor may do. ..Vol. LI., 337. 
 
 CONSIGNATION. See Tender and Payment. 
 
 CONSOLIDATION. See Confusion, 
 
 CONTRACT, 
 
 acceptance inferred from silence... Vol. I., 197. 
 
 acceptance may be tacit... Vol. I., 196. 
 
 accessory... Vol. I., 100. 
 
 agreement to put in writing-... Vol. I., 361. 
 
 aleatory... Vol. I., 28. 91. 
 
 are provisions in marriage contract onerous... Vol. II., 115. 
 
 between third parties may lie proved for collateral purpose... 
 
 Vol. II., 29. 
 bilateral. ..Vol. I., 83 seq. ; Vol. II., 316, 333, 476, 480. 
 bonce fidei... Vol. I., 83, 358. 
 characteristics of, and kinds of. See Table of Contents, Vol. 
 
 I., Chapter IV. 
 commutative... Vol. I.. 91. 
 completion of... Vol. I., 199. 
 conditional. See Conditional Obligations, 
 confirmation of voidable... Vol. I., 215. 
 consensual... Vol. I.. 101. 
 
 creditors, how affected by contract of debtor... Vol. II., 24. 
 damages for revoking offer... Vol. I., 188. 
 definition of. ..Vol. I., 81. 
 
 effects of. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter I. 
 effects of translatory, as between parties... Vol. II., 30. 
 effects of translatory, as regards third parties... Vol. II., 37. 
 formal. ..Vol. I., 101. 
 
 formation of. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapter VII. 
 fraudulent prevention by debtor of fulfilment of condition... 
 
 Vol. II., 341. 
 gratuitous... Vol. I., 95. 
 
 heirs and successors, when bound by... Vol. II., 16 seq. 
 imperfectlv bilateral... Vol. I., 86. 
 implied... Vol. II., 146. 
 incapable party who rescinds, must account for benefit... Vol. 
 
 II., 166. 
 inexistent...Vol. I.. 209. 
 innominate... Vol. I., 98. 
 
 inter prcesentes or inter absentee... Vol. I., 186. 
 involuntary representation in... Vol. II., 15. 
 lapse of offer.. .Vol. I., 193. 
 law governing... Vol. I.. 374. 
 makes law between the parties... Vol. II., 2. 
 modification of, its effect as between parties and against third 
 
 parties... Vol. II., 5 seq. 
 name given to, by parties, is not conclusive... Vol. I., 369. 
 nominate... Vol. I.. 98. 
 offer and acceptance... Vol. I., 186. 
 
 offer, revocation of... Vol. I.. 188. \ 
 
 offer to public. .Vol. I., 187. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 579 
 
 OONTBACT— continued. 
 
 onerous... Vol. I., 97. 
 
 parties to, who are... Vol. II., 13. 
 
 partly executed. See Breach of Contract. 
 
 principal... Vol. I., 100. 
 
 real. ..Vol. I., 102. 
 
 relativity of... Vol. II., 12. 
 
 renewal of. ..Vol. II., 8. 
 
 revocation of acceptance... Vol. I., 204. 
 
 singular successor not affected by... Vol. II., 20. 
 
 synallagmatic... Vol. I., 83, 88; Vol. II., 316, 333, 476, 480. 
 
 telephone, contract made by. . .Vol. I., 204. 
 
 theories of declaration, expedition, and information... Vol. I., 
 200. 
 
 things essential, natural and accidental in. ..Vol. I., 183. 
 
 undertaking to keep offer open ...Vol. I., 191. 
 
 unilateral... Vol. I., 83. 
 
 void and voidable... Vol. I., 207. 210. 
 
 voidable, confirmation of. its effects. ..Vol. I., 220. 
 
 tacit. ..Vol. I., 219. 
 See Breach of Contract; Carrier; Canal; Duress; English 
 Law ; Exoneration, Stipulations of ; Fraud ; German 
 Law; Interpretation of Contracts; Lease of Work; Loan 
 for Use; Mandate; Mistake; Non-performance of Con- 
 tract without Fault of Debtor; Nullity of Contract; Obli- 
 gations ; Partnership ; Paulian Action ; Proof ; Sale ; 
 Stipulation pour autrui ; Swiss Law; Unlawful Contracts. 
 
 CONTRACTOR. See Architect. 
 
 CONTRA NON VALENTEM AGERE NON CURRIT PRE- 
 SCRIPT 'IO... Vol. II., 5.35. 
 
 CONTRE-LETTRES.. .Vol. I., 391; Vol. II.. 124, 129. 
 effect of. ..Vol. II., 129. 
 
 CONVENTIONS... Vol. I., 14. 
 
 CORPORATION. See Person. 
 
 COPYRIGHT. See English Law. 
 
 COUNTER-LETTERS. See Contre-letires. 
 
 CREDITORS, 
 
 chirographic, privileged ami hypothecary... Vol. I., 42. 
 not ayants cause of debtor... Vol. II., 24. 
 not third parties when they sue in debtor's name. ..Vol. II., 
 92. 
 
 See Concordat; Contract; Oblique Action ; Paulian 
 Action. 
 
 CULPA IN CONTRAHENDO... Vol. L, 189. 259, 337. 
 
 CUSTOM. See Interpretation of Contracts. 
 
 •37 (2) 
 
580 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 CUSTOMARY CLAUSES. See Interpretation of Contracts. 
 
 CY-PRES, 
 
 doctrine of. See Phiglish Law. 
 
 DAMAGES. 
 
 compensatory and moratory... Vol. II., 250. 
 
 elements of... Vol. II., 251. 
 
 for breach of contract not. being a contract to pay a sum of 
 
 money. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XIV. 
 for breach of money-debt. See Table of Contents. Vol. JL. 
 
 Chapter XIII. 
 for direct consequences of breach... Vol. II., 255. 
 for moral prejudice... Vol. II., 252. 
 for revocation of offer... Vol. I., 188. 
 
 for what could reasonably have been foreseen... Vol. II., 257. 
 "fraud" of debtor, meaning of. ..Vol. II., 256. 
 "liquidated." See English Law. 
 measure of, in alternative obligation... Vol. II., 374. 
 moratory. See Penal Clause, Obligations with a. 
 not due till debtor is in default... Vol. II., 215. 
 when fraud on part of debtor... Vol. II., 251, 256. 
 
 See Astreintes ; English Law; Exoneration, Stipulations 
 of: German Law; Non-performance of Contract with- 
 out Fault of Debtor; Nullity of Contract; Penal Clause r 
 Obligations with a; Specific Performance; Swiss Law. 
 
 DATE CERTAINE. 
 
 when deed of sale requires... Vol. II., 27. 
 when title must have... Vol. II., 21. 
 when required in lease.. .Vol. II., 23. 
 
 DAT10N EN PAIEMENT.. .Vol. II.. 452. 483. 
 
 DEATH, 
 
 extinguishes certain obligations... Vol. II.. 556, 557. 
 
 DEBTOR. 
 
 exercise of his rights by his creditor.-. See Table of Contents, 
 
 Vol. II., Chapter IV. 
 fraudulent agreement with... Vol. I., 112. 
 
 See Oath: Oblique Action: Paulian Action. 
 
 DECEIT. 
 
 action of. See English Law. 
 
 DECLARATION OF WILL... Vol. I.. 16. 
 DXCONFITURE. See Insolvency. 
 
 DEFAULT. 
 
 conventional, penalty not due until debtor is in.. .Vol. II., 391. 
 effect of default of joint and several debtor... Vol. II., 416. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 581 
 
 DEFAULT, PUTTING IN. See Table of Contents, Vol. LL, 
 
 Chapter XI. 
 causes risk to lie on debtor... Vol. II., 216. 
 fixes time from which damages are due. ..Vol. II., 216. 
 in. commercial matters, usage as to. ..Vol. II., 209. 
 modes of. ..Vol. II., 208. 
 when dispensed with... Vol. II., 210 seq. 
 
 See Damages; English Law; German Law; Swiss Law. 
 
 DECLARATION, 
 
 theory of. See Contract. 
 
 DELAl BE GRACE... Vol. 1., 364; Vol. II., 452. 
 when clause of penalty... Vol. II., 392. 
 
 DELEGATION... Vol. II., 484, 492. 
 
 distinguished from novation... Vol. II., 49.3. 
 
 indication of person to pay or take payment is not. ..Vol. II., 
 
 495. 
 perfect and imperfect. ..Vol. II., 494. 
 
 DELIVERY, 
 
 of determinate thing can be specifically enforced... Vol. II., 
 232. 
 
 See Sal<\ 
 
 DEMANDE RECONVENTIONNELLE. See Compensation. 
 
 DEMOLITION OF WORK, 
 
 can creditor insist on... Vol. II., 229. 
 
 DEFENSES UTILES. See Payment not due. 
 
 DEPOSIT, 
 
 a real contract. ..Vol. I., 103. 
 
 deposit with a bank is a kind of loan... Vol. I., 183. 
 
 depositary cannot plead compensation... Vol. II., 508, 509. 
 
 essentials of contract. ..Vol. I., 183. 
 
 in strong-box. See Lease. 
 
 term, when it is in favour of debtor... Vol. II., 353. 
 
 DEPOSITARY, 
 
 presumption of fault in case of theft from paid depositary... 
 Vol. II., 304. 
 
 DESSAISINE-SAISINE, 
 
 clause of. See Sale. 
 
 DESTRUCTION OF THING PROMISED. See Alternative 
 Obligation. 
 
 DIRECT ACTION. See Paulian Action. 
 
 DISSOLUTION OF OBLIGATION, 
 
 impossibiUty of performance... Vol. II., 476. 
 
 theory of risk... Vol. II., 477, 480. 
 
 unjust enrichment must be returned... Vol. II., 479. 
 
582 INDKX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 DIVISIBLE AND INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. See Table 
 of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXIII. 
 co-heir sued to pay indivisible obligation may call in other 
 co -heirs... Vol. II., 439 seq. 
 comparison between indivisibility and joint and several 
 liability... Vol. II., 442. 
 effect of breach of indivisible obligation with clause of penalty 
 
 when committed by one of co-debtors... Vol. II., 441. 
 obligations indivisible by nature... Vol. II., 432. 
 obligation to produce a completed work is often indivisible... 
 
 Vol. II., 434. 
 obligations which are indivisible as regards performance by 
 debtor only... Vol. II., 435. 
 See English Law. 
 
 DIVORCE, 
 
 law of, cannot be varied by contract. ..Vol. I., 152. 
 
 DOL, 
 
 man cannot stipulate immunity for. ..Vol. II., 261. 
 See Fraud. 
 
 DOMMAGES-INTERETS. See Damages. 
 
 DONATIO SUB MODO.. .Vol. II.. 54. 
 
 DONATION. See Gift. 
 
 DOWRY, 
 
 is obligation to provide, gratuitous or onerous. ..Vol. I.. 97;. 
 
 Vol. II., 115. 
 is obligation to provide, a natural obligation. ..Vol. I., 33. 
 
 DROITS. See Rights. 
 
 DROIT AU SECRET... Vol. I., 388. 
 
 DROIT DE SUITE... Vol. I., 9. 
 
 DROIT PROPRE, 
 
 theory of. See Stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 DURESS. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapter XII. 
 extortionate claim for salvage... Vol. I., 301. 
 threat to cut off gas or water... Vol. I., p. 295. 
 
 EFFET DE COMPLAISANCE. See Bill of Exchange. 
 
 ENEMY, 
 
 alien, who is... Vol. I., 125. 
 trading with... Vol. I., 123. 
 
 See English Law; Moral Person; War. 
 
 ENGAGEMENTS... Vol. II.. 142. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 583 
 
 ENGINEERS, 
 
 prescription of sums due to... Vol. II., 536, 538. 
 
 ENGLISH LAW, 
 
 actio de in rem verso, analogies with... Vol. II., 197. 
 
 acts ultra vires... Vol. I., 351. 
 
 alimony supplied by person not liable for it... Vol. II., 199. 
 
 alleged agent who had no authority... Vol. II., 52. 
 
 arbitration, clause of... Vol. I., 147. 
 
 carrier, can passenger by railway travel at own risk. ..Vol. II., 
 
 283. 
 carrier of passengers is not an insurer. ..Vol. II., 272. 
 carriers liability to passenger without a ticket. ..Vol. II., 267. 
 compensation of debts not automatic... Vol. II., 515. 
 condition, fulfilment of, prevented by debtor.. .Vol. II.. 344. 
 conditions in restraint of marriage... Vol. I., 161. 
 contract, affects parties only... Vol. II., 89. 
 
 breach of, when concurring with tort. ..Vol. II., 266. 
 
 bj r insolvent debtor, giving preference... Vol. I., 113. 
 
 completion of... Vol. I.. 203. 
 
 '■consideration'' in... Vol. I., 63. 
 
 contained in several writings... Vol. I., 391. 
 
 effect of impossibility of performance... Vol. II., 
 
 320 seq. 
 estoppel in. ..Vol. I., 270. 274, 276, 284. 
 ma}' be an implied term of, that some specific person 
 
 or thing shall continue to exist. ..Vol. II., 320. 
 measure of damages for breach of. ..Vol. II., 255, 
 
 2-VJ. 
 not to prosecute... Vol. I.. 137. 
 requires good faith... Vol. I.. 359. 
 rescission of, for fraud... Vol. I., 329. 
 to resign official post.. .Vol. I., 134. 
 To surrender parental rights... Vol. I., 155. 
 unlawful motive in... Vol. I., 62. 
 contracts, indivisibility in... Vol. II., 431. 
 
 in restraint of wills... Vol. I., 163. 
 uberrima fidei...\~o\. I., 330. 
 voidable, confirmation of... Vol. I., 224. 
 void, voidable, and unenforce able... Vol. I., 214. 
 copyright in letter... Vol. I., 388. 
 cop3 T rig"ht of photograph... Vol. I., 381. 
 covenant by vendor of business not to compete, available 
 
 for sub-purchaser... Vol. II., 23. 
 culpa in contrahendo, not recognised in... Vol. I.. 340. 
 cy-pres, dootrine of. ..Vol. II., 3. 
 
 damage wrongously caused, must it always be made 
 good... Vol. I., 336. 
 damages limited to pecuniary loss. ..Vol. II., 55. 
 
 "liquidated," cannot be varied by Court.. .Vol. II., 
 401. 
 deceit, action of... Vol. I.. 322. 
 default, not necessary to put debtor in... Vol. II., 218. 
 
384 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 ENGLISH LAW— continued. 
 
 duress in... Vol. I., 305. 
 
 enemy, trading- with... Vol. I., 124. 
 
 equitable power to rectify instruments... Vol. I., 275. 
 
 equity, fusion of Courts of, with Courts of common law... 
 
 Vol. I., 321. 
 fraud and misrepresentation. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., 
 
 Chapter XIV. 
 fraud in Courts of equity... Vol. I., 352. 
 funeral expenses, payment of, by person not liable... Vol. II., 
 
 199. 
 gaming- contracts... Vol. I., 31. 
 general average, in. ..Vol. II., 173, 197. 
 gestion d'affaires, not a rule of... Vol. II., 197. 
 imputation of payments in... Vol. II., 470. 
 indivisible obligation to produce complete work... Vol. II., 
 
 435. 
 innkeeper, liability for goods of guest. ..Vol. II., 327. 
 insurance for wife and children... Vol. II., 86. 
 interest on money debt. ..Vol. II., 249. 
 lease of house for prostitution... Vol. I., 116. 
 lecture, right to restrain publication of... Vol. I., 389. 
 marriage brokage contracts... Vol. I., 120. 
 marriage, conditions in restraint of. ..Vol. I.. 161. 
 marriage, promise of, made by married man... Vol. I., 116. 
 marriage, separation deed between spouses... Vol. I., 153. 
 misrepresentation. See Fraud and Misrepresentation, 
 mistake. See Table of Contents, Vol. I.. Chapter IX. 
 mistake in telegram... Vol. I., 265. 
 mistake of one party to contract... Vol. I., 237. 
 Moneylenders Acts... Vol. I., 363. 
 natural obligation not known to... Vol. I., 39. 
 offer to contract, revocation of. ..Vol. I., 191. 
 
 tacit acceptance of... Vol. I., 197. 
 lapse of. ..Vol. I., 194. 
 officials, contract to bribe. ..Vol. I., 133. 
 passenger may agree to travel at own risk... Vol. II., 273. 
 penalty stipulated may be reduced... Vol. II., 401. 
 possessor of immoveable, money spent by... Vol. I., 39. 
 prescribed debt, payment of. ..Vol. I., 39. 
 prospectus, false statement in. ..Vol. I., 327. 
 quasi-contracts in. ..Vol. II., 197. 
 railway companies, can only impose reasonable conditions... 
 
 Vol. II., 283. 
 sale and lease combined... Vol. II., 36. 
 sale of business... Vol. II., 23. 
 sale, risk in. ..Vol. II., 477. 
 salvage... Vol. II., 162, 198. 
 set-off, plea of... Vol. II., 515. 
 shipowner may exonerate himself from liability for captain 
 
 ...Vol. II., 283. 
 specific performance, how en forced... Vol. II., 243. 
 stipulation pour autrui not part of. ..Vol. II., 89. 
 stipulations of oxonnration by employer... Vol. II., 282. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 085 
 
 ENGLISH LAW— -continued. 
 
 third party who pays debt lias in general no recourse... Vol. 
 
 II., 197 seq., 447. 
 trade, agreements in restraint of. ..Vol. I., 170. 
 traders, combinations of, illegal... Vol. I., 174. 
 trading with enemy. ..Vol. I., 125, 131. 
 trust compared with stipulation pour autrui... Vol. II., 90. 
 undue influence... Vol. I., 305, 3'66. 
 waiver of tort in... Vol. II., 200. 
 war as excuse for non-performance of contract... Vol. II., 320, 
 
 321, 322, 324. 
 Workmen's Compensation Acts, contracting out of, prohibited 
 
 ...Vol. II., 282. 
 
 EPIDEMIC. See Sickness. 
 
 EQUITY. See English Law. 
 
 ERROR. See Mistake; Payment not Due. 
 
 ESTOPPEL. See English Law. 
 
 EVICTION, 
 
 what amounts to, as point of departure of prescription of 
 action in warranty... Vol. II., 533. 
 
 EVIDENCE. See Proof. 
 
 EXCEPT10 iVOA' ADIMPLETl CONTRACTUS... Vol. I., 88; 
 Vol. II., 4, 222. 
 See German Law. 
 
 EXECUTION. See interpretation of Contracts; Performance. 
 
 EXONERATION FROM LIABILITY, STIPULATIONS OF. 
 
 See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XV. 
 ayence de renseignements... Vol. II., 282. 
 carrier, French jurisprudence as to... Vol. II., 268. 
 forwarding agent... Vol. II., 263. 
 
 gross negligence of self or prepose... Vol. II., 261, 263. 
 negligence, may one stipulate immunity for, or that of pre- 
 
 pose... Vol. II., 264. 
 post-office, can it make as to letters... Vol. II., 276. 
 quasi-delict, may one stipulate immunity for. ..Vol. II., 267. 
 shipowner... Vol. II., 275. 
 
 telegraph company, can it avail itself of... Vol. II., 277, 278. 
 workman, can he contract out of right to claim damages for 
 
 industrial accident... Vol. II., 279. 
 
 See American Law: English Law; German Law; Swiss 
 Law. 
 
 EXPEDITION, 
 
 theory of. See Contract. 
 
 EXPENSES. See Actio de in rem verso; Payment not Due. 
 
686 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 EXPRESSIO UNWS EST EXCLUSIO ALT ERIUS... Vol I., 
 399 . 
 
 EXPROMISSION. ..Vol. LJ., 484. 
 
 EXTINCTION OF OBLIGATIONS. See Obligations Extinc- 
 tion of. 
 
 FACTORS AND BROKERS. ..Vol. II., 14. 
 
 FACULTATIVE OBLIGATION. See Table of Contents, Vol. 
 II., Chapter XX. 
 its .effects... Vol. II., 379. . 
 obligation with penal clause is not. ..Vol. II., 385. 
 
 FAILLITE. See Bankruptcy. 
 
 FAIT DV PRINCE. ..Vol. II., 306. 
 
 FAIT PERSONNEL. See Astreintes ; Specific Performance. 
 
 FAULT. See Breach of Contract; Damages; Faute Contractu- 
 elle ; Fortuitous Event ; Non -performance, of Contract 
 without Fault of Debtor. 
 
 FAUTE CONTRACTU ELLE\ 
 
 distinction between, and faute del ietaelle... Vol. II., p. 265. 
 in law of carriage of passenger... Vol. II., 272. 
 See English Law. 
 
 FAUTE LOURDE. See Gross Negligence. 
 
 FAUTE BE SERVICE... Vol. II., 277. 
 
 FIRE. See Fortuitous Event; Lease of House. 
 
 FORCE MAJEURE, 
 
 explained... Vol. II., 288. 
 
 FORTUITOUS EVENT, 
 
 compared with "act of God "...Vol. II., 326. 
 
 effects of proof of... Vol. II., 316. 
 
 event not fortuitous if brought about by act of debtor... Vol. 
 
 II., 294. 
 fire is not necessarily fortuitous... Vol. II., 299. 
 force majeure, must it be distinguished from... Vol. II., 291. 
 German law as to... Vol. II., 289. 
 onus of proof of... Vol. II., 315. 
 
 See Theft; Fire. 
 Quebec law a-- to. ..Vol. II., 289. 
 strike not always a. ..Vol. II., 314. 
 sudden illness is not, when obligation is to pay money... 
 
 Vol. II., 295, 303. 
 Swiss law as to. ..Vol. II., 289. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 587 
 
 FORTUITOUS EVENT— continued. 
 
 war is not necessarily... Vol. II., 307. 
 what is... Vol. II., 288. 
 
 when does war amount to... Vol. II., 308 seq. 
 See German Law; Quebec Law; Swiss Law. 
 
 FORWARDING AGENT, 
 
 may stipulate his non-liability for acts of carriers. ..Vol. II., 
 263. 
 
 FRAUD. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapters XIII., XIV 
 
 meaning of term in breach of contract... Vol. II., 256. 
 vendor's praise of wares is not... Vol. I., 310. 
 See English Law. 
 
 FREEDOM OF CONTRACT, 
 
 law favours... Vol. I., 105, 362. 
 
 FREEDOM OF TRADE. See Trade. 
 
 FUNERAL EXPENSES, 
 
 claim for repayment of, in English law... Vol. II., 199. 
 See G est ion d'affaires. 
 
 FUNGIBLES. See Sale. 
 
 FUTURE CROPS, 
 
 sale of... Vol. I., 69. 
 
 GAMING CONTRACT, 
 
 does it create natural obligations... Vol. I., 28. 
 in English law. ..Vol. I., 31. 
 
 right to repetition of payments under. ..Vol. I., 31, 177. 
 See Aleatory Contract. 
 
 GENEALOGIST. See Actio de in rem verso. 
 
 GENERAL AVERAGE, 
 
 is principle of, confined to maritime law... Vol. II., 173. 
 See Actio de in rem verso ; English Law. 
 
 GENUS NUNQUAM PERIT... Vol. II., 47<;. 
 
 GERMAN LAW, 
 
 actio de in rem verso in... Vol. II., 185. 
 
 alternative obligation, effect of refusal to make choice in... 
 
 Vol. II., 365. 
 alternative obligation, retroactive effect of choice in... Vol. 11.. 
 
 369. 
 associations in... Vol. II., 313. 
 astredntes in... Vol. II., 243. 
 carrier, liability of. ..Vol. II., 319. 
 compensation of debts, not automatic... Vol. II., 51-5. 
 condition, fraudulent prevention of fulfilment of... Vol. II., 
 
 343. 
 
588 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 GERMAN LAW— continued. 
 
 contract, completion of... Vol. I., '203. 
 
 in restraint of will... Vol. I., 163. 
 
 payments under, unlawful... Vol. I., 176. 
 
 power to vary exorbitant... Vol. I., 365. 
 
 to procure marriage... Vol. I., 121. 
 damages for breach of pecuniary obligation, may be special 
 
 ...Vol. II., 246. 
 damages for nullity of contract... Vol. I., 341. 
 damages, measure of... Vol. II., 246, 259. 
 default, putting in. ..Vol. II., 217. 
 duress in. ..Vol. I., 304. 
 
 ejixeptk) lion adimpleti contractus... Vol. II., 222. 
 fortuitous event... Vol. II., 289, 319. 
 hotel-keeper's liability for goods of guest. ..Vol. II., 305. 
 imputation of payments... Vol. II., 470. 
 interpretation of contracts... Vol. I., 358. 
 mistake. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapter XI. 
 mistake in marriage... Vol. I., 245. 
 mistake in telegram... Vol. I., 283. 
 offer, binding effect of... Vol. I., 192. 
 offer, lapse of. ..Vol. I., 196. 
 payment of debt by third party... Vol. II., 446. 
 penalty, Court may modify conventional... Vol. II., 401. 
 quasi-contract, does not use term... Vol. II., 145. 
 stipulation of non-liability... Vol. II., 284. 
 stipulation pour autrui... Vol. II., 68, 72, 89. 
 
 GESTI0:\ D'AFFAIRES. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., 
 
 Chapter VII. 
 aliment, furnished by party not liable... Vol. II., 159. 
 capacity, person benefited does not need. ..Vol. II., 157. 
 conditions of... Vol. II., 150 sea. 
 gercvnt, limits of claim by. ..Vol. II,, 155. 
 yerant, must have capacity... Vol. II., 158. 
 mandate, analogy with. ..Vol. II., 149. 
 no claim for, if mone}' was paid ammo do nan di... .Vol. II., 
 
 159. 
 payment of funeral expenses for which defendant was bound 
 
 ...Vol. II., 160. 
 payment of debt of another... Vol. II., 446. 
 ship in peril, assistance to... Vol. II., 160. 
 term not used in Egyptian Code... Vol. II., 140. 
 
 See Actio de In rem verso. 
 
 GIFT, 
 
 capacity to take... Vol. II., 84. 
 
 concealed simulation in. ..Vol. I.. 54. 
 
 informal... Vol. I., 27. 
 
 i^ informal gift an inexistent act... Vol. I., 209. 
 
 possible liability in damages of giver... Vol. I., 87. 
 
 GOOD FAITH, 
 
 contracts require.. .Vol. I., 358, 379. 
 See Transcription. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 589 
 
 GRATUITOUS CONTRACTS. 
 
 distinguished from onerous... Vol. I.. 95. 
 See Paulian Action. 
 
 GROSS NEGLIGENCE, 
 
 man cannot stipulate immunity for his own... Vol. IT., 261. 
 or for gross negligence of prepose... Vol. II.. 20:',. 
 See English Law. 
 
 HARTER ACT. See American Law. 
 
 HEIRS, 
 
 right to make choice in alternative obligation passes to... 
 
 Vol. II., 366. 
 their liability for an indivisible debt of ancestor... Vol. II.. 
 
 438. 
 
 See Confusion. 
 
 HEIRS AND SUCCESSORS. See Contract. 
 
 HOTEL-KEEPERS, 
 
 presumption of fault in case of theft. ..Vol. II.. 304. 
 See English Law: German Law; Swiss Law. 
 
 HOUSEKEEPER, 
 
 claim for payment without contract... Vol. I., 34. 
 
 HYPNOTIC SUGGESTION. ..Vol. I.. 291. 
 
 HYPOTHEC. 
 
 creditors who have inscribed hypothec protected by Mixed 
 Code. ..Vol. II., 117. 
 
 destruction of immoveable hypothecated creates facultative 
 obligation... Vol. II., 379. 
 
 in voidable contract, confirmation of... Vol. I., 223. 
 
 judgment cannot avail as conventional hypothec... Vol. IT., 
 228. 
 
 purchaser of immoveable who (discharges hypothec enjoys sub- 
 rogation... Vol. II., 461. 
 
 HYPOTHECARY OBLIGATIONS... Vol. I.. 42. 
 
 IGNORANTIA JURIS NEMINEM EXCUSAT...Vo\. I., 253. 
 
 IMPOSSIBILITY OF PERFORMANCE. See Dissolution of 
 Obligation. 
 
 IMPROBATION. See Inscription en faux. 
 
 IMPUTATION OF PAYMENTS, 
 
 as applied in case of compensation... Vol. II., 511. 
 rules of... Vol. II., 466 seq. 
 
 when debtor ;t taken by surprise "...Vol. II., 468. 
 which debt is most onerous... Vol. II., p. 469. 
 See English Law; German Law; Swiss Law. 
 
£,<)() INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 INCAPABLE PERSON. See Capacity; Actio de in rem verso. 
 
 INCAPACITY. See Capacity. 
 
 INDIRECT ACTION. See Oblique Action. 
 
 INDIVISIBLE OBLIGATIONS. See Divisible and Indivisible 
 Obligations. 
 
 INFORMATION, 
 
 theory of. See Contract. 
 
 INNKEEPER. See Hotel-keeper. 
 
 INNOMINATE CONTRACTS... Vol. I., 97. 
 examples of... Vol. I., 99. 
 
 IN PARI CAUSA POSSESSOR POTIOR HABERI DEBET 
 ...Vol. II., 115. 
 
 IN REM VERSUM... Vol. I., 355. 
 
 IN RE OBSCURA MELIUS EST FAVERE REPETITION! 
 QUAM ADVENTITIO LUCRO... Vol. II., 193. 
 
 INSCRIPTION EN FAUX..No\. II., 126. 
 
 INSOLVENCY, 
 
 effect of insolvency of one of co-debtors after release of the 
 
 debt.. .Vol. II., 424 seq. 
 of non-trader makes debt with a term instantly exigible... 
 
 Vol. II., 356. 
 protection of rights of conditional creditor... Vol. II., 337. 
 
 INSURANCE, 
 
 insurance money, when it forms part of succession... Vol. II., 
 
 64, 71, 75 seq. 
 is policy interpreted against insurer... Vol. I., 396. 
 life-insurance for benefit of third party is stipulation pour 
 
 autrui. . . Vol. II., 63. 
 modification of clause that premiums shall be portables... 
 
 Vol. II., 5. 
 of ship lost or not lost... Vol. I., 93. 
 
 See Aleatory Contracts, 
 subrogation in... Vol. II., 460. 
 waiver of right to claim without mise en demeure...Vol. II., 
 
 214. 
 
 See Stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 INTEREST. 
 
 necessary for action... Vol. I., 80. 
 
 See Compound Interest; Damage^; Moratory Interest; 
 Usurv. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 091 
 
 INTERPRETATION OF CONTRACTS. See Table of Con- 
 tents, Vol. I., Chapter XVIII. 
 clause may be read out of contract... Vol. I., 391. 
 contracts require good faith... Vol. I., 358. 
 customary clauses implied... Vol. I., 377. 
 execution best guide to... Vol. I., 371. 
 is question of fact. ..Vol. II., 4. 
 usage as guide to... Vol. I., 374. 
 
 JHERING, 
 
 theory of culpa in contrahendo. . . .Vol. I., 189. 
 
 JOINT OBLIGATION AND JOINT AND SEVERAL OBLI- 
 GATION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXII. 
 
 acknowledgment of debt by joint and several debtor... 
 Vol. II., 41G. 
 
 characteristics of joint and several liability... Vol. II., 408. 
 
 compensation, failure of co-debtor to plead... Vol. II., 511. 
 
 when pleaded in action by joint-creditor... 
 Vol. II., 405. 
 
 conventional joint and several liability... Vol. II., 413. 
 
 creditor can sue joint and several debtor for whole debt... 
 Vol. II., 414. 
 
 debtor sued by co-creditor can set up compensation only to 
 amount of plaintiff's share... Vol. II., 405 . 
 
 default of co-debtor, its effects... Vol. II., 416. 
 
 defences or " exceptions " available to joint and several debtor 
 ...Vol. II., 417 seq. 
 
 interruption of prescription as against one of joint and several 
 debtors... Vol. II., 416. 
 
 interruption of prescription as to one creditor benefits them 
 all, but otherwise as to suspension... Vol. II., 406. 
 
 joint and several debtor may call in other debtors in warranty 
 ...Vol. II., 414. 
 
 joint and several debtor who pays debt has generally a right 
 of recourse... Vol. II., 429. 
 
 joint and several liability by law... Vol. II., 410. 
 
 joint and several liability compared with liability in indivi- 
 sible obligation... Vol. II., 442. 
 
 liability for costs of action not' necessarily joint and several 
 ...Vol. II., 412. 
 
 novation, effect of. ..Vol. II., 491. 
 
 " personal exceptions "...Vol. II., 417, 418. 
 
 release of the debt... Vol. II., 428. 
 
 release from solidarity... Vol. II., 424. 
 
 renunciation of prescription by one of joint and several 
 debtors does not prejudice others... Vol. II., 550. 
 
 share of liability extinguished by confusion... Vol. II., 519. 
 
 JUDGMENT, 
 
 when it is equivalent to performance... Vol. II., 227. 
 
 JURE NATURE .EQUUM EST NEMINEM CUM 
 ALTERIVS DETRIMENTO ET INIURIA FIERI 
 
 LOCUPLETIOFEM . . .Vol. II., 163. 
 
592 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 JURISDICTION, 
 
 od.nfcracts( to give... Vol. I., 139. 
 contracts to oust... Vol. I., 142. 
 See Prorogation of Jurisdiction. 
 
 JUS OFF ERENDI... .Vol. II., 461. 
 
 LATENT DEFECTS. See Sale. 
 
 LAW. OBLIGATIONS RESULTING FROM THE LAW 
 SOLELY. See Table of Contents. Vol. II., Chapter X. 
 
 LAWYERS. See Advocates; Pactum de quota litis. 
 
 LEASE, 
 
 and sale combined... Vol. II., 36. 
 
 assignment of, contrasted with sub-lease... Vol. II.. 55. 
 cannot be for life. ..Vol. I., 165. 
 claim against occupier who has no. ..Vol. II., 169. 
 destruction of thing let by fortuitous event... Vol. II., 317. 
 grant, of rights to extract products from soil is not lease... 
 ° Vol. I., 370. 
 
 lessee must make use contemplated... Vol. I., 378. 
 lessor's obligation continuous... Vol. I., 49. 
 of house, repairs by lessee... Vol. I., 185. 
 of strong-box... Vol. I., 184. 
 of thing, not perpetual... Vol. I., 7. 
 purchaser, when bound by. ..Vol. II., 23. 
 tenant's repairs... Vol. I., 373. 
 
 war as fortuitous event excusing perfo nuance of. ..Vol. II., 
 308, 309, 310, 311, 312. 
 
 LEASE OF HOUSE, 
 
 presumption in France that fire is by fault of lessee... Vol. II., 
 
 300. 
 presumption, no such in Egypt. ..Vol. II., 301. 
 
 LEASE OF WORK, 
 
 terminates by death of workman... Vol. II., 19. 
 
 war as excuse for non-performance... Vol. II., 308, 312. 
 
 when contract may be cancelled... Vol. II., 10. 
 
 LECTURER, 
 
 right to restrain publication of lecture... Vol. I., 389. 
 See English Law. 
 
 LEGITIMACY, 
 
 contract to abandon claim as to... Vol. I., 156. 
 
 LESION, 
 
 enorme lesion not ground of challenge... Vol. I., 94. 
 minor's action for supplement of price... Vol. I., 94. 
 See Minors. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 59o 
 
 LETTEK, 
 
 contract formed by... Vol. I., 186 seq. 
 rights in... Vol. I., 385, 386, 387. 
 
 See English Law; Exoneration from Liability; Stipula- 
 tions of; Mistake. 
 
 LIQUID OBLIGATIONS... Vol. I., 44. 
 
 LIQUIDATED DAMAGES. See English Law. 
 
 LOAN, 
 
 when is term in favour of debtor. ..Vol. II., 353. 
 
 LOAN FOE USE, 
 
 a real contract... Vol. I., 103. 
 
 borrower who has made improper use is liable for loss without 
 
 being put in default... Vol. II., 213. 
 liability of lender... Vol. I., 86. 
 right of retention... Vol. I., 90. 
 lender can claim thing for urgent need... Vol. II., 11. 
 
 LOCATION -VENTE. See Lease. 
 
 LOI RABIER... Vol. II., 269. 
 
 LOTTERIES, 
 
 contract of partnership in... Vol. I., 111. 
 
 LUNATICS, 
 
 contracts by... Vol. I., 25, 348. 
 
 •MANDATE, 
 
 gratuitous mandatary's liability for gross fault... Vol. I., 96 
 
 implied, of joint and several deb tors... Vol. II., 415, 421. 
 
 is it confined to juridical acts... Vol. II., 162. 
 
 is often implied... Vol. II., 146. 
 
 its relation with gestion d'affaires... Vol. II., 149. 
 
 mandatary who employs sums for his own profit is liable 
 
 without being put in default... Vol. II., 213. 
 may be revoked or renounced... Vol. II., 10. 
 power to vary remuneration... Vol. I., 364-. 
 right to renounce... Vol. I., 7. 
 
 tacit mandate of wife in French law... Vol. II., 169. 
 telegraph company as mandatary... Vol. I., 261. 
 terminates by death of either party... Vol. II., 557. 
 when is mandatary bound personally... Vol. II., 13. 
 
 MARITIME LAW. See Carrier; English Law; Exoneration; 
 Stipulations of; General Average; Gestion d'affaires; 
 Salvage. 
 
 MARRIAGE, 
 
 conditions in restraint of... Vol. I., 157. 
 
 second marriage . . . Vol . I . , 160. 
 contract cannot alter law of... Vol. I., 151; Vol. II., 9. 
 w. — vol. ii. 38 
 
594 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 MARRI AG E — continued. 
 
 contract restricting... Vol. I., 157. 
 contract to procure... Vol. I., 117. 
 mistake as to person in... Vol. I., 241. 
 See English Law; German Law. 
 
 MARRIED WOMAN, 
 
 loan to, without husband's authorisation, in French law... Vol. 
 II., 163. 
 
 See Mandate. 
 
 MEDICAL MAN, 
 
 contract with, for life... Vol. I., 166. 
 See Physician. 
 
 MINORS, 
 
 contracts by... Vol. I., 25, 347 seq. 
 
 proof of lesion not necessary in Mohammedan law... Vol. I., 
 
 353. 
 renunciation of prescription by... Vol. II., 548. 
 when they can confirm contract... Vol. I., 218. 
 
 See Capacity; Mohammedan Law. 
 
 MISE EN DEMEVBE. See Default, Putting in. 
 
 MISREPRESENTATION. See English Law. 
 
 MISTAKE. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapters IX., X., 
 XI. 
 as ground of nullity of contract... Vol. I., 228. 
 as to substance... Vol. I., 230. 
 
 is it cause of nullity in unilateral contract... Vol. I., 235. 
 of one party only... Vol. I., 236. 
 
 See English Law; German Law: Swiss Law. 
 
 MODALITIES, 
 
 of obligations... Vol. I., 40. 
 
 MODIFICATION OF CONTRACT BY PARTIES... Vol. II., 7. 
 
 MOHAMMEDAN LAW. 
 
 alimentary provisions... Vol. II., 203. 
 
 minors, acts of... Vol. I., 353. 
 
 no confusion between estate of heir and estate of ancestor... 
 
 Vol. II.. 520. 
 renunciation of prescription by minor. ..Vol. II., 548. 
 suspends prescription when good excuse for inaction... Vol. 
 
 II., 556. 
 u-alxfs and successions, special period of prescription as to... 
 
 Vol. II., 523. 
 
 MONEY DEBT. See Table of Contents. Vol. II., Chapter XIII. 
 MONEYLENDERS ACTS. See English Law. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 59.5 
 
 MORAL PERSON, 
 
 can it be alion enemy... Vol. I., 127. 
 exists for certain purposes only... Vol. II., 166. 
 See Capacity; Persons. 
 
 MORAL PERSONALITY, 
 
 criticism of theory... Vol. I., 349. 
 
 MORATORY INTEREST, 
 
 prescribes in five years... Vol. II., 525. 
 
 MORTGAGE. See Hypothec. 
 
 MUNICIPAL COMMISSIONS, 
 are they persons... Vol. I.. 344. 
 
 ^NATURAL OBLIGATIONS IN EGYPTIAN LAW... Vol. I., 
 21 seq. • 
 
 See Table of Contents, Vol. I.. Chapter I. 
 no repetition of payment under... Vol. I., 177. 
 
 See Accessory Contract; Dowry; Gaming Contract; Nova- 
 tion; Payment not Due; Suretyship. 
 
 NECESSARIES. ..Vol. II., 199. 
 See Aliment. 
 
 NEGATIVE INTEREST.. .Vol. I., 339. 
 theory of... Vol. I., 286. 
 
 NEGLIGENCE. 
 
 stipulations excluding liability for. ..Vol. II., 264. 
 See Gross Negligence. 
 
 NEGOTIORUM GESTIO. See Ge.slhu d'affaires. 
 
 NEMO AUDITUR TURPITUDINEM SUAM ALLEGANS... 
 Vol. I., 177. 
 
 NEMO PLUS JURIS TRANSFERRE POTEST QUAM IPSE 
 HABERET...\o\. II., 20. 
 
 NEMO POTEST PEMCISE COGl AD FACTUM. ..Vol. II., 
 230. 
 
 NOTARY, 
 
 improbation of deed by... Vol. II.. 126. 
 
 NOVATION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXIV. 
 distinguished from assignment of claim. ..Vol. II., 495. 
 its effect on joint and several debt... Vol. II., 491. 
 its nature... Vol. II., 482. 
 
 not necessarily involved in delegation... Vol. II., 493. 
 of natural obligation... Vol. I., 35. 
 proof of... Vol. II., 486. 
 
 38 (2) 
 
596 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 NOVATION— continued. 
 
 transfer of securities... Vol. II., 489. 
 
 when is official instrument necessary to affect third parties... 
 Vol. II., 491. 
 See Delegation; Expromission. 
 
 NON-LIABILITY, CLAUSES OF. See Exoneration, Stipu- 
 lations of. 
 
 NON-PERFORMANCE OF CONTRACT WITHOUT FAULT 
 OF DEBTOR. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter 
 XVI. 
 debtor who foresees impossibility must do his best. ..Vol. II., 
 296. 
 
 See Fortuitous Event. 
 
 NUL NE DOIT S'ENBICHIB INJUSTEMENT AVX DEPENS 
 D'AUTBUI... Vol. II., 140. 142, 163. 
 
 NULLITY. See Contract, 
 
 NULLITY OF CONTRACT, DAMAGES FOR. See Table of 
 Contents, Vol. I., Chapter XV. 
 effect of annulling- contract for mistake... Vol. I.. 259. 
 
 OATH, 
 
 of debtor who invokes short prescription... Vol. II., 528. 
 
 OBJECTS OF OBLIGATIONS, 
 character of. ..Vol. I., 17. 
 
 determination of, in contracts other than sale. ..Vol. I., 77. 
 distinguished from object of contracts... Vol. I., 64. 
 future succession... Vol. I., 71. 
 future things. ..Vol. I., 68. 
 lawfulness of. ..Vol. I., 79, 104. 
 must be an act... Vol. I., 65. 
 object of commerce... Vol. I.. 72. 
 of aleatory contracts... Vol. I., 93. 
 possibility of... Vol. I., 78. 
 qualities of... Vol. I., 66. 
 
 OBLIGATION DE BONNER.. .Vol. I., 17: Vol. II., 30. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS, 
 
 arising- without agreement, ..Vol. I., 14; Vol. II.. 140 seq. 
 
 See Quasi-contract, 
 cause of... Vol. I., 48. 
 
 See Cause, 
 civil and natural... Vol. I., 20 seq. 
 
 See Natural Obligations, 
 conditional. See Conditional Obligations, 
 conjunctive and alternative... Vol. II., 361. 
 effects of. distinguished from effects of contracts... Vol. II., 1. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 597 
 
 OBLIGATIONS— continued. 
 
 extinction of. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXIV. 
 See Compensation ; Confusion ; Dissolution ; Novation ; 
 Payment; Performance; Prescription; Release. 
 how created... Vol. I., 13 seq. 
 in which there are several objects and .several subjects. See 
 
 Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XIX. 
 objects of. See Objects of Obligations, 
 obligation defined... Vol. I., 1. 
 obligation not to do... Vol. I., 18. 
 obligation to do... Vol. I., 18. 
 
 See Specific Performance, 
 obligation to give... Vol. I., 17, 67. 
 obligation to transfer... Vol. I., 17. 67. 
 
 See Contract, 
 of conscience... Vol. I., 20. 
 
 are not legal obligations... Vol. I., 21. 
 See Natural Obligations, 
 resulting from the law solely. See Table of Contents, Vol. 
 
 II., Chapter X. 
 simple and composite... Vol. II., 361. 
 simple and multiple... Vol. II., 362. 
 
 sources and classes of. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., 
 Chapter I. 
 
 See Alternative Obligations; Conditional Obligations ; 
 Contract ; Divisible and Indivisible Obligations ; 
 Facultative Obligations; Joint Obligations and Joint 
 and Several Obligations; Natural Obligations; Penal 
 Clause, Obligations with a; Personal Eights; Term, 
 Obligations with a; Unlawful Contracts. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS SOLIDAIRES. See Joint Obligations and 
 Joint and Several Obligations. 
 
 OBLIQUE ACTION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter 
 
 IV. 
 creditors can bring without judgment against debtor... Vol. 
 
 II., 96. 
 creditors can plead prescription in favour of their debtor... 
 
 Vol. II., 549. 
 creditors cannot bring action which is purely personal... Vol. 
 
 II., 100 seq. 
 creditors do not need to be subrogated... Vol. II., 96. 
 creditors do not need to have anterior claims... Vol. II., 98. 
 must be to increase assets of debtor... Vol. II., 97. 
 not essential that debtor shall be mis en cause. ..Vol. II., 96. 
 
 See Debtor. 
 
 OFFER. See Contract. 
 
 OFFICIALS, 
 
 bribes of, whether recover able... Vol. I.. 180. 
 contracts to bribe. ..Vol. I., 133. 
 contracts to resign post... Vol. I., 133. 
 
 OFFTtES REELLES. See Tender and Payment. 
 
598 JNDEX TO BOTH VOLUMK8. 
 
 PACTS, 
 
 in Roman law... Vol. I., 58. 
 
 PACTUM DE QUOTA LITIS... Vol. I., 134. 
 
 PAINTER, 
 
 cannot be compelled to complete picture... Vol. II., 231. 
 nature of contract for picture... Vol. I., 380, 381. 
 See Astreintes; English Law; Picture. 
 
 PARTNERSHIP, 
 
 contract by partner in own name... Vol. II., 165. 
 
 dissolved by death of partner... Vol. II., 557. 
 
 lender to partner is not necessarily partner... Vol. I., 370. 
 
 may be renounced... Vol. II., 10. 
 
 no compensation between debt due to, and debt due by- 
 partner... Vol. II., 502. 
 
 publication of, when necessary... Vol. II., 28. 
 
 right to retire from... Vol. I., 7. 
 
 secret, claim against partner's who have received benefit... 
 Vol. II., 174. 
 
 when partner is liable to pay damages in excess of interest 
 for delay in contribution... Vol. II., 247. 
 
 when partner liable jointly and severally... Vol. II., 411. 
 See Persons. 
 
 PATERNAL AUTHORITY, 
 
 contract to infringe... Vol. I., 153. 
 
 is legal administration essential part of... Vol. I., 155. 
 
 PAULIAN ACTION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., 
 Chapter V. 
 
 challenge of premium on insurance... Vol. II., 87. 
 
 conditions required for... Vol. II., 107. 
 
 creditors may challenge debtor's renunciation of a prescrip- 
 tion if in fraud... Vol. II., 549. 
 
 distinction between onerous and gratuitous acte... Vol. II., 114. 
 
 does it affect sub-purchaser... Vol. II., 116. 
 
 fraud presumed in gratuitous alienation by insolvent... Vol. 
 II., 108. 
 
 is it action of nullity... Vol. II., 117, 121. 
 
 preferential payment is not " fraud "...Vol. II., 110. 
 
 prescription of... Vol. II., 123. 
 
 rules of, differ from those of action to find deed simulate... 
 Vol. II., 137. 
 
 subsequent creditors cannot bring 1 . ..Vol. II., 112. 
 
 what is fraud on creditors in onerous contract... Vol. II., 113. 
 
 who takes benefit of... Vol. II., 120. 
 
 PAYMENT. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXIV. 
 cannot prejudice a seizure. ..Vol. II., 451. 
 if without reserve is renunciation of prescription... Vol. II. , 
 545. 
 
INDEX TO MOTH VOLUMES. 599 
 
 P A Y M ENT— torttmusd . 
 
 meaning- of, in Egyptian codes... Vol. II., 444. 
 
 proof of. ..Vol. II., 454. 
 
 to incapable person. ..Vol. II., In6, 449. 
 
 See Ballon en paiement ; English Law; German Law; 
 Imputation of Payments; Performance; Tender and 
 Payment. 
 
 PAYMENT NOT DUE, 
 
 claim of receiver for necessary and beneficial expenses... Vol. 
 II., 196. 
 
 payment of natural obligation by debtor who thinks he is 
 
 bound civilly... Vol. II., 194. 
 quasi-contract arising- from. See Table of Content's, Vol. II., 
 
 Chapter IX. 
 receiver in good faith can keep fruits... Vol. II., 19.3. 
 when error was cause of payment... Vol. II., 189. 
 
 PAYMENT WITH SUBROGATION. See Subrogation. 
 
 PECUNIARY OBLIGATION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., 
 Chapter XIII. 
 
 PENAL CLAUSE, OBLIGATIONS WITH A. See Table of 
 
 Contents, Vol. II., Chapter XXI. 
 are accessoiy...Vol. II., 386. 
 are not alternative... Vol. II., 384. 
 cannot be used to evade law as to maximum rate of interest... 
 
 Vol. II., 394. 
 damages in excess of penalty may be given in cases of 
 
 ''fraud" or gross fault... Vol. II., 394. 
 definition of penal clause... Vol. II., 382. 
 is penalty recoverable if creditor has suffered no damage... Vol. 
 
 II., 397 seq. 
 nullity of penalty does not annul principal obligation... Vol. 
 
 II.,' 388. 
 penalty cannot in principle be modified... Vol. II., 392. 
 penalty comes in place of damages... Vol. II., 389. 
 penalty fixed for delay... Vol. II., 389. 
 penaltv may be reduced in case of part-performance... Vol. 
 
 II., 395. 
 penalty nut due without fault or default... Vol. II., 391. 
 what if obligation is indivisible and one of co-debtors fails 
 
 to perform it... Vol. II., 441. 
 
 See English Law; German Law; Swiss Law. 
 
 PENALTY. See Astreintes; Penal Clause, Obligations with a. 
 
 PERFORMANCE, 
 
 impossibility of, may be objective or subjective... Vol. II., 
 
 290. 
 made to person holding- the right to claim execution... Vol. 
 
 II., 449. 
 
600 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 PERFOEMANCE— continued. 
 
 must be of thing due and cannot be made in part... Vol. II., 
 
 451. 
 supervening' impossibility of. ..Vol. II., 287. 
 what is... Vol. II., 144. 
 when it must be made. ..Vol. II., 452. 
 "who can make. ..Vol. II., 445. 
 
 See Breach of Contract; Non-performance of Contract with- 
 out Fault of Debtor; Payment; Specific Performance; 
 Substituted Performance; Tender and Payment. 
 
 PERSONS. See Table of Contents, Vol. I., Chapter XVI. 
 of the public law... Vol. I., 344. 
 partnership is a person. ..Vol. I., 341. 
 restricted capacity of moral persons... Vol. I., 350. 
 See Capacity; Moral Persons. 
 
 PERSONAL RIGHTS, 
 
 ambiguity of term... Vol. I., 12. 
 can they be perpetual... Vol. I., 7. 
 explanation of... Vol. I., 5. 
 
 PHOTOGRAPHER, 
 
 nature of contract with. ..Vol. I., 99, 380, 381, 382, 383. 
 
 PHYSICIAN, 
 
 prescription of sums due to. ..Vol. II., 536. 
 
 PICTURE, 
 
 declaration of authorship of, by vendor... Vol. II., 22. 
 mistake as to painter of... Vol. I., 237. 
 See Painter. 
 
 PL EDO E, 
 
 contract of, is accessory... Vol. I., 100. 
 delivery essential... Vol. I., 183. 
 
 pledgee protected by rale possession vaut titre...\o\. II., 45. 
 requires delivery... Vol. I., 370. 
 
 surrender of thing pledged is not release of debt... Vol. II., 
 498. 
 
 PORTE-FORT, 
 
 compared with agent who exceeds authority... Vol. II., 52. 
 contract of. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter II. 
 contract of, distinguished from surety ship... Vol. II., 49, 50. 
 
 PORTRAIT, 
 
 nature of contract to paint. ..Vol. I., 99. 
 See Painter. 
 
 POSSESSIOX VAUT TITRE...Yo\. II., 34, 43, 44, 133, 338. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. (301 
 
 POSSESSOR IN BAD FAITH, 
 
 liable for loss of thing - without being put in default. . .Vol. II., 
 
 213. 
 may have to restore fruits for fifteen years. ..Vol. II., 524. 
 
 POSSESSOR IN GOOD FAITH. See Payment not Due; 
 Possession mut litre. 
 
 POST OFFICE. See Letter; Telegram. 
 
 PREPOSE. See Exoneration from Liability, Stipulations of. 
 
 PRESCRIPTION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter 
 XXIV. 
 acquisitive and extinctive... Vol. II., 521. 
 by five years... Vol. II., 524. 
 360 days. ..Vol. II., 527. 
 fifteen years... Vol. II., 523. 
 creditors can take plea of... Vol. II., 549. 
 extinctive, none of right of property in immoveable... Vol. I., 
 
 212. 
 interruption of... Vol. II., 551 seq. 
 
 as against one of joint and several debtors... 
 
 Vol. II., 416. 
 as to one joint creditor benefits all... Vol. II., 
 
 406. 
 its effects... Vol. II., 553. 
 must bo pleaded... Vol. II., 530. 
 oath, when debtor must take. ..Vol. II., 528. 
 of challenge of voidable contract... Vol. I., 211, 213. 
 of conditional debtor, or of debt subject to a term... Vol. II., 
 
 533. 
 of debts to "tradesmen "...Vol. II., 534. 
 of obligation by possessor to restore fruits... Vol. II., 524. 
 of Paulian action... Vol. II., 123. 
 of purchaser's action in warranty, runs from "eviction"... 
 
 Vol. II., 533. 
 of sums due to advocates and engineers... Vol. II., 536 seq. 
 of sums due to physicians... Vol. II., 536. 
 period of, how reckoned... Vol. II.. 530. 
 
 not changed bv debtor giving bill of exchange... 
 
 Vol. II., 487. 
 reckoned bv Arab or by Gregorian calendar... 
 Vol. II., 539. 
 pleaded at any stage... Vol.. II., 529. 
 
 renunciation of, agreement to suspend, is not. ..Vol. II., 543. 
 as to time already run. ..Vol. II., 544. 
 by one of joint and several debtors does 
 
 not prejudice others... Vol. II., 550. 
 cannot be made in advance... Vol. II., 541. 
 capacity required for. ..Vol. II., 548. 
 is not alienation... Vol. II., 547. 
 ma}- be tacit... Vol. II., 544 seq. 
 may creditors challenge... Vol. II.. 549. 
 
602 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 PRESCRIPTION— continued. 
 
 retroactive effect of... Vol. II., 538. 
 serment de credulite...Vo\. II. , 528. 
 suspension of... Vol. II., 553. 
 
 ;i^ against one joint creditor does not benefit 
 
 the others. ..Vol. II., 406. 
 by fortuitous event. ..Vol. II., 290, 555. 
 is it created bv impossibility to sue... Vol. II., 
 554. 
 wdkj* and successions in Mohammedan law. ..Vol. II., 523. 
 
 PRET A LA GROSSE.. .Vol. I., 92. 
 
 PRETE-NOM. See Simulation. 
 
 PRICE, 
 
 mistake as to... Vol. I., 246. 
 
 PRINCIPAL OBLIGATIONS... Vol. I., 43, 100. 
 
 PRIVILEGE OF VENDOR, 
 
 does beneficiary in stipulation pour autrui enjoy it... Vol. II.,. 
 72. 
 
 PRIVILEGED OBLIGATIONS... Vol. I., 42. 
 
 PROCEDURE, 
 
 renunciation of rights connected with... Vol. I., 138. 
 when debtor's oath required... Vol. II., 528. 
 See Prescription; Proof. 
 
 PROMISE OF SALE. See Sale. 
 
 PROOF, 
 
 by witnesses, of clerical mistake.:. Vol. I., 250. 
 
 by witnesses, renunciation of objection to.. .Vol. I., 148. 
 
 clause of exoneration considered as shifting onus of... Vol. IL, 
 
 268. 
 exclusion of, by contract... Vol. I., 150. 
 fraud proved by witnesses... Vol. I., 319. 
 not allowed of negotiations prior to contract... Vol. I., 367. 
 of a payment not due... Vol. II., 191. 
 
 of circumstances in which contract was made... Vol. I., 369. 
 of contract between third parties, when alio wed... Vol. II., 29. 
 of novation... Vol. II., 486. 
 of payment... Vol. II. , 454. 
 of quasi-contracts... Vol. II., 146. 
 of simulation of deed... Vol. II., 127. 
 
 PROPERTY, 
 
 transfer of, in alternative obligation... Vol. II., 368. 
 when it passes by contract... Vol. I., 73, 75; Vol. II., 30, 37. 
 See Sale. 
 
 PROPOSITION '. See Offer. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 603 
 
 PROROGATION OF JURISDICTION, 
 
 contracts as to... Vol. I., 139. 
 
 PROSPECTUS, 
 
 false statement in... Vol. I., '-V11 . 
 
 PROSTITUTION, 
 
 lease of house for. ..Vol. I., 115, 180. 
 
 PUBLIC OFFICIALS, 
 
 promises of reward to... Vol. I., Ill, 180. 
 
 PUBLIC POLICY... Vol. I., 45. 
 
 in law of carriage of goods... Vol. II., 273. 
 in regard to contracts with carrier... Vol. II., 271. 
 rights given by law based on, cannot be renounced... Vol. I.„ 
 107 seq. 
 
 See Cause; Unlawful Contracts. 
 
 PUBLISHER, 
 
 contract that he is not to be liable for libel... Vol. I., 111. 
 See Author. 
 
 PURGE. ..Vol. II., 462. 
 
 its effect when debtor alienates immoveable hypothecated... 
 Vol. II., 359. 
 
 QUASI-CONTRACTS... Vol. I., 15; Vol. II., 140. 
 
 compared with obligations resulting from the law solely... 
 
 Vol. II., 201. 
 criticism of term... Vol. II., 143. 
 proof of... Vol. II., 146. 
 
 See Actio de in rem verm; English Law; German Law; 
 Gestion d'affaires; Payment not Due. 
 
 QUASI-DELICTS. ..Vol. I., 15. 
 
 QUEBEC LAW, 
 
 mistake... Vol. I., 232. 
 
 unlawful contracts, right to repeat payment... Vol. I., 181. 
 
 QUI DOIT GARANTIE NE PEUT MINCER. ..Vol. II.. 520 
 
 QUI FACIT PER ALIUM FACIT PER SE... Vol. II., 13. 
 
 QUI HAERET IN LITERA HAERET IN CORTICE... Vol. I., 
 367. 
 
 QUI PAIE MAL PAIE DEUX FOIS... Vol. II., 449. 
 
 RAILWAY, 
 
 no action by railway company for increased value created by 
 construction of. ..Vol. II., 164. 
 See Carrier. 
 
(J04 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 .RATIFICATION. See Confirmation. 
 REAL CONTRACTS... Vol. I., 102. 
 
 REAL RIGHTS, 
 
 can be set up against successors of author of. ..Vol. II., 26. 
 
 RECEIVER IN BAD FAITH. See Possessor in Bad Faith. 
 
 RELEASE FROM JOINT AND SEVERAL LIABILITY, 
 
 to what extent it may be pleaded by joint and several debtor 
 ...Vol. II., 422 seq. 
 
 RELEASE OF DEBT, 
 
 its nature. ..Vol. II., 496. 
 
 joint creditor cannot grant... Vol. II., 406. 
 
 one of co-heirs of creditor in indivisible obligation cannot 
 
 grant release of debt... Vol. II., 439. 
 when implied... Vol. II., 497. 
 
 See Joint Obligation and Joint and Several Obligation. 
 
 REMISE DE LA DETTE. See Release of Debt, 
 
 REPETITION, 
 
 of money paid under gaming contracts... Vol. I., 31. 
 
 of payment not due. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter 
 
 IX. 
 of payments on contract with unlawful cause... Vol. I., 175 
 
 seq. 
 
 REPETITION DE LTNDU. See Payment not Due. 
 
 REPRESENTATION. See Contract, 
 
 RESCISSION, 
 
 of contract, for breach... Vol. II., 221. 
 
 See Capacity; Duress; English Law; Fraud; Mistake. 
 
 RESOLUTION. See Rescission. 
 
 RESOLUTORY CONDITION. See Condition. 
 
 RESPONSABILITE DU TIERS COMPLICE... Vol. II., 28. 
 
 RETENTION, 
 
 has negotmmm gestor right of... Vol. II., 157. 
 right of... Vol. I., 90. 
 
 RETROACTIVITY. See Alternative Obligation; Conditional 
 Obligation. 
 
 RIGHTS, 
 
 absolute and relative... Vol. I., 5. 
 
 legal... Vol. I., 3. 
 
 of preference... Vol. I., 9. 
 
 personal and purely personal... Vol. I., 13. 
 
INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 605 
 
 RISK, 
 
 debtor may have undertaken all risks. ..Vol. II., 2«<; 
 
 in conditional obligations... Vol. II., 348. 
 
 in obligations to transfer... Vol. II., 477 seq. 
 
 of thing paid which was not due... Vol. II., 195. 
 
 on debtor who is in default. ..Vol. II., 216. 
 
 theory of, in Egyptian law... Vol. II., 217, 480. 
 
 See Dissolution of Obligation; English Law; Exoneration 
 from Liability, Stipulations of. 
 
 RISQUE CREE, 
 
 theory of... Vol. II., 291. 
 
 RISQUE PROFESSIONNEL... Vol. II., 280. 
 
 SALE, 
 
 combined with lease... Vol. II., 36. 
 
 condition of, fraudulently prevented by debtor... Vol. II., 348. 
 
 contract of, when interpreted against seller... Vol. I., 393. 
 
 co-vendors liable jointly and severally for fraudulent declara- 
 tions. ..Vol. II.,' 411.' 
 
 co-vendors' obligation to deliver may be joint and several... 
 Vol. II., 413. 
 
 damages for loss of profit... Vol. II., 251. 
 
 damages in case of sale of property not .seller \s...Vol. I., 339. 
 
 date certaine, when purchaser must have deed with... Vol. II.. 
 27. 
 
 delivery, buyer who claims, must tender price unless credit 
 given... Vol. II., 222. 
 
 delivery not needed to pass property... Vol. II., 32. 
 
 dessaisine-saisine, clause of... Vol. II., 32. 
 
 destruction of one or both of two things sold alternativelv... 
 Vol. II., 375. 
 
 destruction of thing sold. ..Vol. II.. 476 seq. 
 
 determination of object of... Vol. I., 73. 
 
 essential mistake in... Vol. I., 233. 
 
 essentials of... Vol. I., 183. 
 
 innominate contract resembling... Vol. I., 100. 
 
 judgment may be equivalent to deed of. ..Vol. II., 228. 
 
 latent defect in thing... Vol. I., 266. 
 
 minor, action by, for supplement of price... Vol. I., 94. 
 
 misrepresentation in English law... Vol. I., 325. 
 
 mistake as to person in... Vol. I., 239. 
 
 nature of contract of, in Roman law... Vol. I., 73. 
 
 not essential that property should pass at once... Vol. II., 35. 
 
 object not existing at date of... Vol. I., 49, 67. 
 
 obligations of vendor and purchaser reciprocal... Vol. I., 49. 
 
 of book debts... Vol. I., 95. 
 
 of determinate thing... Vol. I., 74. 
 
 of fungibles... Vol. I., 75. 
 
 of future successions... Vol. I., 71. 
 
 of future things. ..Vol. I., 68,94. 
 
 of land after contract to grant servitude... Vol. II., 19. 
 
4j<)6 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 SALE — continued. 
 
 of property leased... Vol. II., 23. 
 
 of right to extract products from soil. ..Vol. I., 371. 
 
 of ship, proof of... Vol. II., 31. 
 
 of thing not belonging to seller... Vol. II., 34. 
 
 passing of property in.. .Vol. I., 73, 75; Vol. II., 30, 37. 
 
 privilege of vendor, does beneficiary under stipulation pour 
 antral enjoy... Vol. II., 72. 
 
 purchaser succeeds to action against architect... Vol. II., 22. 
 
 risk in... Vol. II., 217, 477, 480. 
 
 seller must declare latent deled*... Vol. I., 312. 
 
 subrogation, when purchaser of immoveable enjoys... Vol. II., 
 461. 
 
 unilateral promise to buy... Vol. I., 85. 
 
 unpaid seller cannot sue donee of purchaser... Vol. II., 165. 
 
 vendor's promise in sale of business not to compete with pur- 
 chaser available for sub -pur chaser... Vol. II., 22. 
 
 war as fortuitous event excusing performance... Vol. II., 310, 
 311. 
 
 warranty, action of, passes to sub-purchaser... Vol. II., 22. 
 
 warranty, seller may giant longer period than legal delay... 
 Vol. II., 542. 
 
 See Assignment of Claims; Duress; English Law; Fraud; 
 Mistake; Paulian Action; Eisk; Trading; Trading with 
 Enenry ; Transcription . 
 
 SALES BY AUCTION, 
 
 illegal interference with... Vol. I., 171. 
 
 SALVAGE. See Duress; Ges-lio)t d'affaires; English Law. 
 
 sECUEITIES, 
 
 impairment of, by debtor... Vol. II., 359. 
 
 SEIZUEE, 
 
 payment cannot prejudice... Vol. II., 451. 
 
 SRXATUSCONSULTUM MACEd6nIANUM...VcA. I.. 23. 
 
 REPARATION DBS PATRIMOINES, 
 
 its effects... Vol. II.. 438. 
 
 SERMENT DE CREDULITE. See Prescription. 
 
 SEEVICE, 
 
 contract of... Vol. I., 6. 
 
 <KEVITUDE, 
 
 exclusion of warranty as to. ..Vol. I.. 372. 
 of public interest, cannot be renounced... Vol. I., 108. 
 promise to grant can be enforced specifically... Vol. II., 232. 
 servitude of passage i< indivisible... Vol. II., 
 433. 
 so-called "legal " servitudes, criticism of worn. ..Vol. II., 202. 
 See Sale. 
 
[NDEX TO HOT!! VOLUMES. 607 
 
 SETTLEMENT, 
 
 scheme of, binds creditors who did not consent... Vol. II., 16. 
 
 SET-OFF. See Compensation; English Law. 
 
 SHIP. See Gesticm d'affaires; Maritime Law; Sale. 
 
 SHIPOWNERS. See Carrier. 
 
 SICKNESS, 
 
 when it is fortuitous event... Vol. II., 302. 
 
 SIMULATION. See Table of Contents, Vol. II., Chapter VI. 
 action of, differs from oblique action. ..Vol. II., 139. 
 does judgment affect sub-purchasers... Vol. II., 135, 136. 
 effect of judgment upon hypothecary creditor... Vol. II., 134. 
 not in itself cause of nullity... Vol. II., 125. 
 proof of.. .Vol. II., 127. 
 
 rules different from those of Paulian Action. ..Vol. II., 137. 
 who are third parties... Vol. II., 131. 
 
 SINGULAR SUCCESSORS. See Contract. 
 
 SLAVE, 
 
 contract by, in Roman law. ..Vol. I.. 23. 
 
 SOLIDAR1TE. See Joint Obligation and Joint and Several 
 Obligations . 
 
 SOLIDARITY, IMPERFECT, 
 theory of... Vol. II., 428. 
 
 SOLVENCY, 
 
 mistake as to... Vol. I., 241. 
 
 SPECIFIC PERFORMANCE, 
 
 can creditor always claim demolition of works. . .Vol. II., 229. 
 not of fait personnel.. Vol. II., 225, 229. 
 of promise to deliver... Vol. II., 232. 
 of promise to grant lease. ..Vol. II., 233. 
 of promise to grant servitude... Vol. II., 232. 
 of promise to sell... Vol. II., 228. 
 of promise to transfer shares... Vol. II., 233. 
 See Astreintes. 
 
 SPOLIATUS ANTE OMNIA RESTITUENDUS... Vol. II., 507. 
 
 STATUS, 
 
 mistake as to.... Vol. I., 242. 
 natural obligations arising from... Vol. I., 32. 
 obligations of, result from the law solely... Vol. II., 202. 
 rights of... Vol. I., 4. 
 
 STIPULATION FOR BENEFIT OF THIRD PARTIES. See 
 Stipulation pour autrui. 
 
608 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 STIPULATION POUR AVTRVI. See Table of Contents, Vol. 
 
 II.. Chapter TIL 
 are "heirs" determinate perspns...Vol. II., 82. 
 assurance collective... Vol. II., 79. 
 effecd <>(' stipulation for payment to third party, or, in default, 
 
 for payment of penalty to stipulator... Vol. II., 387. 
 in contracts for public works. ..Vol. II.. 56. 
 in contracts of public utility... Vol. II., 57. 
 in insurance... Vol. II., 55. 
 lease, assignment of, is... Vol. II., 55. 
 
 may beneficiary lie indeterminate or future. ..Vol. II., 76 seq. 
 public subscription may be. ..Vol. II., 58. 
 theories of, discussed... Vol. II., 60 seq. 
 
 See English Law. 
 
 STOCKBROKERS. See Factors and Broker-. 
 
 STOCK EXCHANGE, 
 
 gambling on... Vol. I., 30. 
 
 STRIKE, 
 
 not necessarily valid excuse for non-performance of contract... 
 Vol. II., 314. 
 
 STRONG-BOX, 
 
 contract to lease... Vol. I., 184. 
 
 SUBROGATION, 
 
 differences between French and Egyptian laws... Vol. II., 457. 
 
 differs from assignment of claims... Vol. II., 458. 
 
 effects of.. .Vol. II., 463. 
 
 is there a new debt... Vol. II., 464 seq. 
 
 legalised document not required by Native Code... Vol. II., 
 
 459. 
 nature of... Vol. II., 455. 
 when legal subrogation occurs... Vol. II.. 460. 
 
 SUBSCRIPTIONS. See Stipulation pour autrui. 
 
 SUBSTANCE, 
 
 difference between mistake as to substance and latent defect... 
 Vol. L, 266. 
 See Mistake. 
 
 SUBSTITUTED PERFORMANCE, 
 
 must Court grant, if demanded... Vol. II., 227. 
 when available... Vol. II., 227. 
 
 SUCCESSION SEARCHERS... Vol. I., 121. 
 
 SURETY, 
 
 can he claim damages in excess of interest... Vol. II., 247. 
 can plead compensa f ion with debt due by plaintiff to prin- 
 cipal debtor... Vol. II., 502. 
 
• Index to both volumes. 609 
 
 SURETY— continued. 
 
 can secure natural obligation... Vol. I., 100. 
 discharged if debt is extinguished by confusion... Vol. 11.. ,")18. 
 exceptions which he can plead. -..Vol. II., 418. 
 judicial, joint and several liability of... Vol. II., 410. 
 See Release of Debt. 
 
 SURPRISE, 
 
 imputation when debtor was "taken by surprise "...Vol. II., 
 468. 
 
 SWISS LAW, 
 
 an actio de in rem verso in... Vol. II., 185. 
 
 compensation, no automatic, in... Vol. II., 515. 
 
 completion of contract... Vol. I., 203. 
 
 condition, effect of preventing fulfilment of... Vol. II., 343. 
 
 damages for breach of money -debt... Vol. II., 247. 
 
 damages for mistake in contract... Vol. I., 262. 
 
 default, putting in... Vol. II., 218. 
 
 fortuitous event in.. .Vol. II., 318. 
 
 hotel-keeper's liability for goods of guest... Vol. II., 305. 
 
 interpretation of contracts... Vol. I., 358. 
 
 mistake in marriage... Vol. I., 245. 
 
 mistake in transmission of offer or acceptance... Vol. I., 262, 
 
 283. 
 offer, binding effect of... Vol. I., 192. 
 offer, lapse of... Vol. I., 195. 
 penalty, Court may modify. ..Vol. II., 40l. 
 stipulation pour autrui...Vo\. II., 72. 
 stipulations of non-liability... Vol. II., 285. 
 threats by third party.. .Vol. I., 299, 303. 
 
 SYNALLAGMATIC CONTRACT. See Bilateral Contract. 
 
 SYNDIC AT. See Trades-Union. 
 
 TAX, 
 
 payment of tax illegally imposed... Vol. II., 189, 190. 
 
 TELEGRAM, 
 
 damages for mistake in. ..Vol. I., 259. 
 stipulations of non-liability... Vol. II., 277. 
 See English Law; German Law. 
 
 TELEPHONE. See Contract. 
 
 TENDER AND PAYMENT, 
 
 made at bar of Court... Vol. II., 474. 
 of specific corporeal thing... Vol. II., 471 seq. 
 when necessary... Vol. II., 470. 
 
 when obligation is to do, to deliver an immoveable, or to 
 deliver an indeterminate thing... Vol. II., 474 seq. 
 
 w. — vol. ii. 39 
 
610 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 TERM, OBLIGATION WITH A. See Table of Contents, Vol! 
 II., Chapter XVIII. 
 
 cannot be compensated with exigible debt if term is in favour 
 
 of debtor... Vol. II., 504. 
 definition of. ..Vol. II., 350. 
 
 diminution of securities by debtor, effect of. ..Vol. II., -350. 
 bow right to claim term may be lost. ..Vol. II., 355 seq. 
 bow term is computed. ..Vol. II., 351. 
 if debtor pays lias be right to repetition... Vol. II., 351. 
 implied in contracts... Vol. I., 363. 
 prescription of... Vol. II., 533. 
 risk during term... Vol. II., 351. 
 what acts can creditor do... Vol. II., 351. 
 when is term presumed to be in favour of debtor... Vol. II., 
 
 353. 
 
 TESTAMENT. See Wills. 
 
 THEFT, 
 
 may be fortuitous event. ..Vol. II., 303. 
 See Carrier; Depositary; Hotel-keeper. 
 
 THIEF, 
 
 bound to restore without being put in default. ..Vol. II., 213. 
 
 THIRL) PARTIES. See Contract; Transcription. 
 
 THREATS. See Duress. 
 
 TITLE TO DEBT, 
 
 effect of destruction of, by creditor... Vol. II., 190. 
 
 TRADE, 
 
 contracts in restraint of... Vol. I., 163. 
 refusal to trade, when unlawful... Vol. I., 164. 
 See Trading. 
 
 TRADE SECRET, 
 
 disclosure of... Vol. I., 360. 
 
 " TRADESMEN," 
 
 meaning of term in law of prescription... Vol. II., 535. 
 
 TRADES-UNION, 
 
 contract that workman shall not belong to... Vol. I., 167. 
 
 TRADING, 
 
 restrictions as to, in sale of business... Vol. I., 166. 
 
 TRADING WITH ENEMY... Vol. I., 123 seq. 
 See Enemy. 
 
 TRADITIONIBUS ET USUCAPIONIBUS DOMINI A RERUM, 
 NON NVDIS PACTIS TRANSFERUNTUR...Vo\. II., 
 32. 
 
Index To both volumes. km 
 
 Transcription, 
 
 does not cure vice of title... Vol. II., 110. 
 
 of lease, when necessary... Vol. II., 23. 
 
 protection of purchaser in good faith. ..Vol. II., 20. 
 
 protects against contre-lettre not registered... Vol. II., 133. 
 
 what purchasers are protected by. ..Vol. II., 39. 
 
 when is purchaser in good faith. ..Vol. II., 41, 42, 43. 
 
 TRUST. See English Law. 
 
 TUTORSHIP, 
 
 law of, cannot be varied by contract... Vol. I., 154. 
 
 ULTRA VIRES. See English Law. 
 UNDUE INFLUENCE. See English Law. 
 
 UNJUST ENRICHMENT, 
 
 incapable person must account for... Vol. I., 355. 
 
 See Actio de in rem verso; Dissolution of Obligation. 
 
 UNLAWFUL CONTRACTS. See Table of Contents, Vol. 1., 
 
 Chapter V. 
 contract against public policy by lex fori not enforceable... 
 
 Vol. I., 370. 
 contract not unlawful because exorbitant... Vol. I., 105. 
 right to challenge cannot be lost by acquiescence... Vol. II., 7. 
 
 See Exoneration, Stipulations of; Gaming' Contract. 
 
 USAGE. See Default, Putting in; Interpretation of Contracts. 
 
 USURY, 
 
 laws against... Vol. I., 28. 
 
 laws as to, cannot be evaded by penal clause... Vol. II., 383, 
 
 394. 
 payment of usurious interest, when recoverable... Vol. I., 178. 
 See Damages; Compound Interest. 
 
 VENTES 2 TEMPJERAMENT ...\o\. II., 30. 
 
 VERBA CONTRA STIPULATOREM INTERPRET AN DA 
 SUNT. ..Vol. I., 394. 
 
 VIOLENCE. See Duress. 
 
 VOLENTI NON FIT INJURIA.. .Vol. II., 281, 282. 
 
 WAIVER OF TORT. See English Law. 
 
 WAR, 
 
 debtor may have taken risk of war into account... Vol. II., 280. 
 See Enemy; Fortuitous Event. 
 
612 INDEX TO BOTH VOLUMES. 
 
 WIFE. See Married Woman. 
 
 WILL, 
 
 contract in restraint of... Vol. I., U>2. 
 damage* for preventing... Vol. I., 289. 
 informal... Vol. I., 27/ 
 
 WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION ACT. See English Law. 
 
 WRONGDOERS, 
 
 when liable jointly and severally... Vol. II., 410. 
 
 LONDON: PEINTED BY 0. F. ROWORTH, 88, FETTER LANE, E.C. 
 
JULY, 1920. 
 
 A 
 
 SELECTION 
 
 OF 
 
 RECENT LAW WORKS 
 
 PUBLISHED BY 
 
 STEVENS & SONS, Limited, 
 
 119 & 120, CHANCERY LANE, LONDON, W.C.2. 
 
 %* A Discount of 20 per cent, off all new Books 
 (except where marked net) for Cash with Order. 
 (Carriage or Postage extra.) 
 
 Complete Catalogue of New. and Secondhand Law Works post free. 
 
 ABC GUIDE TO THE PRACTICE OF THE SUPREME 
 COURT, 1920. Net, 7s. 6d. 
 
 "Of great service to the profession." — Solicitors' Journal. 
 
 ACCOUNTS.— Hodsoll's Practical Accounts for Execu- 
 tors and Trustees. 1914. Net, 10s. 6d. 
 
 " Invaluable to law and accountancy students, solicitors and 
 others.'' — Law Times. 
 
 ADMIRALTY.-Roscoe's Admiralty Practice. Fourth 
 Edition. (Incorporating- Williams and Brace's Admi- 
 ralty Practice. ) 1920. Net, 21. 2s. 
 
 ADVOCACY.— Harris' Hints on Advocacy.— Fifteenth 
 Edition. 1920. 10, Sl 
 
 " Deserves to be carefully read by the young barrister whose 
 career is yet before him." — Law Magazine. 
 
 AGRICULTURAL LAW.-Spencer's Agricultural Hold- 
 ing Acts. Fifth Edition. With Notes. 1911 to 1915. 8s. 
 Spencer's Small Holdings and Allotments Acts.— 
 With Notes. Second Edition. 1920. 10 5 . 
 
 Spencer's Corn Production Act, 1917.— Annotated and 
 Explained. 1918. 5 S . 
 
 ANNUAL COUNTY COURTS PRACTICE, 1920. 
 
 Net, 11. 10s. 
 "It admirably fulfils the essential requisites of a practice 
 book." — Law Times. 
 
 ANNUAL DIGEST, 19f9. \ c t 15 S 
 
 ANNUAL PRACTICE, 1920. Net, 11. 10s. 
 
 " A. book which t-yi ry practisiug English lawyer must have." 
 . . . — Law Qiiarterhi Review. 
 
 ANNUAL STATUTES, 1919. Net, It. Is. 
 
ARBITRATION.— Russell on the Power and Duty ot art 
 Arbitrator. — Tenth Edition. By A, &. Hudson, K.O. 
 1919. Net, 21. 2s. 
 
 AVERAGE.— Lowndes' Law of General Average.— Fifth 
 Edition. By E. L. de Hart and G. R. Rudolf. 1912. 
 
 11. 16s. 
 
 BANKING.— Hart's Law of Banking.— Third Edition. 
 1914. 1/. 125. 
 
 BANKRUPTCY.— Aggs' Handbook on Bankruptcy. 1915. 
 
 Net, 4s. 
 
 Lawrance's Deeds of Arrangement, with Precedents. 
 
 Eighth Edition. By Sydney E. Williams. 1914. 7s. 6d. 
 " Concise, practical, and reliable." — Law Times. 
 
 Williams' Law and Practice in Bankruptcy.— 
 
 Eleventh Edition. By E. W. Hansell and M. E. 
 Hansell. 1915. 11 16s. 
 
 BILLS OF EXCHANGE.— Chalmers' Bills of Exchange. 
 
 Eighth Edition. By Sir M. D. Chalmers, K.C.B., 
 C.S.I. , and Kenneth Chalmers. 1919. 11. 10s. 
 
 BUILDING SOCIETIES.-Wurtzburg's Law relating to 
 Building Societies.— Fifth Edition. 1920. 20s. 
 
 CARRIERS.— Carver's Treatise on the Law relating to 
 
 the Carriage of Goods by Sea.— Sixth Edition. By 
 
 James S. Henderson. 1918. 21. 2s. 
 
 " The standard modern book on carriage by sea." — Law Quarterly. 
 
 Disney's Law of Carriage by Railway.— Fourth Edi- 
 tion. 1915. 7s. 6d. 
 
 " Can be cordially recommended to the lawyer."— Law Times. 
 
 CHANCERY.— Daniell's Chancery Practice.— Eighth Edi- 
 tion. By Sydney E. Williams and F. Guthrie-Smith. 
 2 vols. 1914. 51. 5s 
 
 Daniell's Chancery Forms and Precedents.— Sixth 
 
 Edition. By R. White, F. E. W. Nichols and H. G. 
 Garrett. 1914. 21. 10s. 
 
 " The two volumes on Practice and the one volume of Forms 
 constitute together a most valuable work on the practice of the 
 Chancery Division." — Law Quarterly Review. 
 
 CHECKWEIGHING.— Cockburn's Law of Checkweigh- 
 ing. 1919. 7s. 6d. 
 
 COLLISIONS AT SEA.— Marsden's Collisions at Sea.— 
 
 Seventh Edition. By Marcus W. Slade. 1919. 1/. 15s. 
 " Indispensable for Admiralty practitioners." — Law Journal. 
 
 COMPANY LAW.— Palmer's Company Law. A Practical 
 Handbook for Lawyers and Business Men. Tenth Edi- 
 tion. By Alfred F. Topham. 1916. Net, 15s. 
 
COMPANY LAW— continued. 
 
 Palmer's Company Precedents.— Eleventh Edition. 
 Parti. General Forms. 1912. " Net, 21. 10s. 
 
 " Palmer's works on Company Law are all beyond criticism." 
 — Law Magazine. 
 
 Palmer's Private Companies.— Thirty-second Edition. 
 1920. ' Net, Is. 
 
 Palmer's Shareholders', Directors', and Voluntary 
 Liquidators' Legal Companion. — Thirtieth Edition. 
 1919. Net,2s.6d. 
 
 CONSTITUTIONAL LAW.— Ridges' Constitutional Law 
 of England.— Second Edition. 1915 15s. 
 
 CONTRACTS.— Addison's Law of Contracts— Eleventh 
 Edition. By W. E. Gordon and J. Ritchie. 1911. 
 
 11. 2s. 
 "Among all the works on Contracts, there is none more useful 
 to the practitioner than Addison." — Law Times. 
 
 Leake's Principles of the Law of Contracts.— Sixth 
 
 Edition. By A. E. Randall. 1911. M. 18s. 
 
 "A full and reliable guide to the principles of the English Law 
 of Contract."— Law Journal. 
 
 Pollock's Principles of Contract.— Eighth Edition. 
 1911. !*• 12s - 
 
 " There is no book on the English Law of Contract which deals 
 so lucidly and yet so comprehensively as this." — Law Journal. 
 
 CONVEYANCING. — Armitage's Short Conveyancing 
 Forms. 1918. Net, 12s. 6d. 
 
 Prideaux's Forms and Precedents in Conveyancing. 
 
 — Twenty-first Edition. By B. L. Cherry and R. Bed- 
 dington. 2 vols. 1913. Net, U. 4s. 
 
 "'Prideaux" is the best work on Conveyancing." — Law 
 Journal. 
 
 COVENANTS.— Wurtzburg's Law relating to Covenants 
 for the Settlement of a Wife's After-acquired Pro- 
 perty.— 1912. 5s. 
 
 CRIMINAL LAW. — Archbold on Indictments. — With 
 
 Forms. By H. D. Roome. 1916. 10s. 6d. 
 
 Archbold's Pleading, Evidence and Practice in 
 
 Criminal Cases.— Twenty-fifth Edition. By H. D. 
 
 Roome and R. E. Ross. 1918. Net, 21. 2s. 
 
 Denman's Digest of Criminal Law.— Second Edition. 
 
 1918. Net, 11. 5s. 
 
CRIMINAL LAW— continued. 
 
 Russell's Treatise on Crimes and Misdemeanors.- 
 
 Seventh Edition. By W. P. Craies and L. W. Ker- 
 shaw. 3 vols. 1909. 41. 10s. 
 " Indispensable in every Court of criminal justice here and in 
 our colonies." — 7' he Times. 
 
 DEATH DUTIES.— Webster-Brown's Finance Acts.— 
 (Estate and other Death Duties.) Third Edition. 1915. 
 
 12s. 6d. 
 "Contains much practical advice which will be of substantial 
 assistance to practitioners." — The Times. 
 
 DICTIONARY.— Wharton's Law Lexicon.— Twelfth Edi- 
 tion. By E. A. Wurtzburg. 1916. 21. 10s. 
 "The most useful of legal works." — Law Journal. 
 
 The Pocket Law Lexicon.— Fourth Edition. 1905. 
 
 Net, 6s. 6d. 
 " A wonderful little legal Dictionary." — Law Students' Journal. 
 
 DIGEST.— Mews' Digest to End of 1920. Net, Ul. 
 
 Full Particulars on application. 
 EASEMENTS.— Goddard's Treatise on the Law of Ease- 
 ments.— Seventh Edition. 1910. 11. 10s. 
 " Nowhere has the subject been treated so exhaustively." — Law 
 Times. 
 
 Innes' Digest of the Law of Easements.— Eighth Edi- 
 tion. 1911. 7s. 6d. 
 ELECTIONS.— Rogers' Parliamentary Elections and 
 
 Petitions.— Nineteenth Edition. 1918. Net, 11. os. 
 
 ELECTRICITY.— Knowles' Law relating to Electricity. 
 
 — In two Parts. Part I., Electric Lighting and Power; 
 
 Part II., Electric Traction. 1911. ' 21. 10s. 
 
 The Parts may be had separately, each 11. 5s. net. 
 
 EQUITY.— Seton's Forms of Judgments and Orders. 
 
 With Practical Notes. Seventh Edition. By A. R. 
 Ingpen, K.C., F. T. Bloxam and H. G. Garrett. 
 3 vols. 1912. 61. 
 
 "A most valuable and indispensable work." — Law Journal. 
 
 Smith's Practical Exposition of the Principles of 
 Equity.— Fifth Edition. 1914. 21s. 
 
 " Useful to both practitioner and student alike." — Law Stu- 
 dents' Journal. 
 
 EVIDENCE— Holt's Outline of the Rules of Evidence- 
 
 1917. Net, Is. 
 
 Tregarthen's Law of Hearsay Evidence. — 1915. 
 
 Net, 5s. 
 " An elaborate and detailed account of a very imperfectly 
 understood topic." — Law Quarterly Review. 
 
 Watson's Law of Evidence.— 1917. Net, 12s. 6d. 
 
 EXCESS PROFITS.— Sutcliffe's Excess Profits Duty and 
 
 the Cases Decided thereon. 1919. 7s. 6d. 
 
EXECUTORS.— Ingpen's Law relating to Executors and 
 Administrators. — Second Edition. 1914. Net, 11. 5s. 
 
 "The book may be recommended, with confidence, as accurate, 
 practical, and learned." — Law Quarterly Review. 
 
 Walker's Law relating to Executors and Adminis- 
 trators.— Fifth Edition. 1920. Net, 11. 5s, 
 
 FARM.— Hopkins' Farm Law.— By T. M. Hopkins, Bar- 
 rister-at-Law. 1920. Net,3s.G<l. 
 
 FORMS.— Bowstead's Collection of Forms and. Piece 
 dents other than Conveyancing, Company, Local Govern 
 ment and Practice Forms. — 2 vols. 1914. Net, 21. 10s 
 " An indispensable adjunct to every practising lawyer's 
 library." — Law Journal. 
 
 Chitty's Forms of Civil Proceedings in the King's 
 
 Bench Division.' — Fourteenth Edition. By T. W. 
 
 Chitty, E. EL. Chapman and P. Clark. 1912. 21. 10s. 
 
 " An indispensable adjunct to every working lawyer's library." 
 
 — Law Journal. 
 
 Daniell's Chancery Forms and Precedents.— Sixth 
 
 Edition. By E. White, F. E. W. Nichols and H. G. 
 
 Garrett. 1914. 21. 10s. 
 
 "The standard work on Chancery Procedure."— Law Quarterly 
 
 Review. 
 
 HIRE-PURCHASE SYSTEM— Russell's Practical Manual 
 of Hire-Trade Law.— Fifth Edition. 1914. 7s. 6d. 
 
 "The book ia full of practical suggestions." — Solicitors' 
 Journal. 
 
 INCOME TAX.— Aggs' Income Tax Act, 1918. With Full 
 Notes and an Introduction and Index. 1919. Net, 12s. 6d. 
 
 INDUSTRIAL COURTS.— Stoker on the Industrial 
 Courts Act, 1919. Net 3s. 6d. 
 
 INSURANCE.— Stone's Insurance and Workmen's Com- 
 pensation Cases.— 2 vols. 1914. Net, 21. 2s. 
 
 "A very valuable compendium of the case law of insurance." — 
 Solicitors' Journal. 
 
 INTERNATIONAL LAW.— Anthonis' Sanctions of Inter- 
 national Law. 1917. Net, Is. 
 Wheaton's Elements of International Law.— Fifth 
 English Edition. By Coleman Phillipson, LL.D. 
 With an Introduction by the Right Hon. Sir Frederick 
 Pollock, Bart., D.C.L., LL.D. 1916. 21. 
 " Wheaton stands too high for criticism." — Law Tim**- 
 
LAND VALUES.--Napier's New Land Taxes and their 
 Practical Application. — Second Edition. 1912. 11. Is. 
 
 LANDLORD AND TENANT.— Woodfall's Law of Land- 
 lord and Tenant.— Twentieth Edition. 1920. (Nearly 
 ready.) Net, 21. 15s. 
 
 " Woodfall is really indispensable to the practising lawyer, 
 of whatever degree he may be." — Law Journal. 
 
 LAW LIST, 1920. Net, 12s. Gd. 
 
 LEADING CASES.— Petrides' Student's Cases, illustra- 
 tive of all branches of the Law. 1910. 12s. 6d. 
 "The cases appear to be well chosen and correctly stated." — 
 Solicitors' Journal. 
 
 Randall's Selection of Leading Cases in Equity.— 
 1912. 10s. Gd. 
 
 " One of the foremost, if not the best, of Equity case books." — 
 Law Students' Journal. 
 
 Shirley's Selection of Leading Cases in the Common 
 
 Law.— Ninth Edition. By R. Watson. 1913. 18s. 
 
 " The selection is very large, though all are distinctly ' Leading 
 
 Cases,' and the notes are by no means the least meritorious part 
 
 of the work." — Law Journal. 
 
 LEAGUE OF NATIONS.-Pollock on the League of 
 
 Nations.— By Rt. Hon. Sir Frederick Pollock, Bt. 
 1920. Net, 10s. 
 
 LEGAL HISTORY— Deans' Student's Legal History- 
 Third Edition. 1913. 10s. 
 " There is no better short introduction to the study of the law." 
 — Law Notes. 
 
 LIBEL AND SLANDER.— Ball's Law of Libel as affecting 
 Newspapers and Journalists.— 1912. 6s. 
 
 "A well-arranged and well-executed work." — Law Journal. 
 
 Odgers' Digest of the Law of Libel and Slander.— 
 
 Fifth Edition. 1911. II. 18*. 
 
 " Should be found on the shelves of every practitioner." — Law 
 Students' Journal. 
 
 LUNACY.— Heywood and Massey's Lunacy Practice.— 
 
 Fifth Edition. 1920. 17. 10,?. 
 
 MAGISTRATES' PRACTICE, 1916— By C. M. Atkinson, 
 Stipendiary Magistrate for Leeds. 20s. 
 
 MENTAL DEFICIENCY.— Davey's Law relating to the 
 Mentally Defective.— Second Edition. 1914. 10s. 
 
 "This admirably arranged and handy book." — Law Journal,. 
 
MORTGAGE.— Coote's Treatise on the Law of Mort- 
 gages.— Eighth Edition. By Sydney E. Williams. 
 2 vols. 1912. Net, SI. Ss. 
 
 "It is essentially a practitioner's book, and we pronounce it 
 'one of the best.' " — Law Notes. 
 
 NATIONAL INSURANCE.— Watts on National Insur- 
 ance.— 1913. 12s. Gd. 
 NIGERIA.— Titles to Land in Nigeria.— 191G. Net, 30s 
 
 NOTARY.-- Brooke's Office and Practice of a Notary. 
 
 —Seventh Edition. By J. Cranstoun. 1913. 1/. 10s. 
 
 OBLIGATIONS.— Walton on the Egyptian Law of Obli- 
 gations. A Comparative Study, with special reference 
 to the French and the English Law. 2 Vols. 1920. 
 
 Net, 21. 10s. 
 
 PEACE TREATY.— Picciotto and Wort's Treaty of Peace 
 with Germany: Clauses affecting Mercantile Law. 
 
 1919. Net, 6s. 
 
 PLEADING.— Bullen and Leake's Precedents of Plead- 
 ings.— Seventh Edition. By W. Blake Odgers, K.C., 
 and Walter Blake Odgers. 1915. • 21. 10s. 
 
 "The standard work on modern pleading." — Law Journal. 
 
 Eustace's Practical Hints on Pleading.— 1907. 5s. 
 Odgers' Principles of Pleading and Practice.— Eighth 
 
 Edition. 1918. 15s. 
 
 "The safest possible guide in all matters affecting pleading 
 
 and practice." — Law Journal. 
 
 POOR LAW SETTLEMENT.— Davey's Poor Law Settle- 
 ment and Removal. — Second Edition. 1913. 15s. 
 
 POWERS.— Farwell's Concise Treatise on Powers.— 
 
 Third Edition. By C. J. W. Farwell and F. K. 
 
 Archer. 1916. If 15s. 
 
 PRIVATE BILLS.— Landers' Procedure and Practice 
 
 relating to Private Bills in Parliament. 1919. 
 
 * It. 12s. 
 
 PRIZE CASES.— Cases Decided in the Prize Court and 
 on Appeal to the Privy Council. 
 
 Each Part Net, 7s. 6 d. 
 
 PROFITEERING.— The Profiteering Act, 1919. Fully 
 
 Annotated. By L. W. J. Costello and 11. O'Sullivan. 
 With a Foreword by C. A. McCurdy, K.C., M.P. 
 
 Re-Issue with Addenda, 1920. Net, 5s. 
 
 PROPERTY.— Strahan's General View of the Law of 
 Property.— Sixth Edition. By J. A. Straiian, assisted 
 by J. Sinclair Baxter. 1919. 16s. 
 
ftATINU. — Davey's Law of Rating.— With Supplement 
 
 bringing the Work down to June, 1919. Net, 11. 10s. 
 
 \* The Supplement may be had separately, Net, 5s. 
 
 RECEIVERS AND MANAGERS.— Riviere's Law relating 
 to Receivers and Managers. — 1912. 9s. 
 
 SMALL HOLDINGS.-Spencer's Small Holdings and 
 Allotments Acts.— Second Edition. 1920. 10s. 
 
 STATUTES.— Chitty's Statutes to End of 1920. Net, 171. 
 Full Particulars on application. 
 
 TORTS.— Addison's Law of Torts.— Eighth Edition. By 
 W. E. Gordon and W. H. Griffith. 190G. Net, U. 18s. 
 "Essentially the practitioner's text-book." — Law Journal. 
 
 TRADE UNIONS.— Greenwood's Law relating to Trade 
 
 Unions.— 1911. 10s. 
 
 A Supplement to above, including the Trade Union Act, 
 1913. 1913. Net,Zs.U. 
 
 The two works together, net, 10s. 
 
 TRANSPORT.— Robertson's Ministry ot Transport Act, 
 1919. — With an Introduction and Notes. 6s. 
 
 TRUSTS AND TRUSTEES.— Godefroi on the Law of 
 
 Trusts and Trustees. — Fourth Edition. By Sydney 
 E. Williams; 1915. 11. 16*. 
 
 "An eminently practical and useful work." — Law Times. 
 
 WAR. Higgins' Defensively Armed Merchant Ships.— 
 
 1917. Net, Is. 
 
 Page's War and Alien Enemies.— The Law affecting 
 their Personal and Trading Rights; and herein of Con- 
 traband of War and the Capture of Prizes at Sea. 
 Second Edition. 19 to. Net, 6.9. 6d. 
 
 WILLS. — Theobald's Concise Treatise on the Law of 
 
 Wills.— Seventh Edition. 1908. 2/. 
 
 " Indispensable to the conveyancing practitioner." — Law Times. 
 
 WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION. — Costs under the 
 
 Workmen's Compensation Act. — With Precedents. 
 
 1915. 5s. 
 
 Knowles' Law relating to Compensation for Injuries 
 
 to Workmen.— Third Edition. 1912. 11. 
 
 Workmen's Compensation Reports.— A complete Scries 
 of Keports of Cases on the subject of Workmen's Com- 
 pensation. With Annotated Index. 
 
 Subscription for 1921, 2os. net (pod free). 
 
 STEVENS &l SONS, Ltd., 119 & 120, Chancery Lane, London, 
 
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY 
 
 Los Angeles 
 This book is DUE on the last date stamped below. 
 
 pj-l 
 
 oct 05 m 
 
 20m-7,'67(H3149s4) 
 
3 1158 01202 0284 
 
 AA 000 807 009 6