HF 1756 L93 1922 XX A A JCS 1 J) 1 2 ONA '~ 5 30 1 -ACII =i m E f||l:;:;F:Riii||;;:tWB^A ll/ll)ll^"^llf,T^?.^„9,^V,'^0RNIA SAN DIEGO ^^02201526 0318 miT] T 'irrT^ san d,ego 3 1822015260318 U L Central University Library University of California, San Diego Please Note: This item is subject to recall. Date Due nFH 1 6 1993 jaa'd APR 2 6*94 CI 39 (7/93) UCSDLi). Sincerely yours, Lee Francis Lybarger. TARIFF PRIMER A GRAPHIC PRESENTATION OF THE FORDNEY-McCUMBER TARIFF WHAT IT IS HOW IT WORKS WHOM IT BENEFITS —BY- LEE PRANCIS Ly?AR.GER Member of the Hhiiadelph'a 3ar. Lyceum and GhHutaadua ^--epturer. Formerly President Inter- national Lyoei'm pnd ChartauQua Atsociaiiou of A'nerica. Illustrations by John H. Coakley TARIFF PUBLISHING COMPANY 1819 BROADWAY, NEW YORK Hobson Printiiur Company Eaatoo, Pa. Gopyighted, October, 1922'.- By. Lee Francis .Ly^arger. DEDICATED TO THE RIGHT OF THOSE WHO LABOR IN ALL LANDS AND CLIMES TO SELL THE PRODUCTS OF THEIR LABOR WHERE THEY CAN SELL THE DEAREST AND BUY WITH THEIR WAGES WHERE THEY CAN BUY THE CHEAPEST PREFACE Can a people be enriched by their own taxation? That is the question now confronting the American people. If a people can be enriched by the simple process of taking hundreds of millions of dollars annually out of the pockets of the Many, and pouring them into the huge pockets of the Privileged Feic, then the Fordney-McCumber Tariff is the most beneficient piece of legislation in the History of the Re- public. If it be true that a people can be prospered by so simple a method, then will the new Tarifi lift our toiling mill- ions out of the perils of penury and want, up into the happy realm of abundance. Were the Tariff Issue so clear and definite as above stated, it would of course have disappeared long ago from our political history. No question about that. But it is not. On the con- trary, it is an issue so complex and involved, so mixed up and confused by the multiplied relations sustained even by the average citizen in the complex financial and industrial life of today, that after generations of discussion, we know but little more about the Tariff than we did at the beginning. The heroic and independent spirit.- of our "Sires of '76", would not have considered the toleration of so monstrous and extortionate a measure as the Fordney-McCumber Tariff for a single minute. Their fight was against Taxation : we fight/or Tax- ation. But the real facts in the case — and the dire consequences to the consuming public — were far easier to see then than they are today. Amidst the complexities of our modern civilization, the fact as to who pays and who gets — as to who are the Tariff's beneficiaries and who its victims — can now be disguised, con- fused and hidden in a thousand different ways. The Author's interest in this subject began far back in boy- hood days, when a student in the High School. More years of my life have been given to the study of the theory and the effects of a Protective Tariff — and of that universal thing, called Trade, which the Tariff seeks to obstruct— than to any other one problem connected with the general welfare. Added to these years of study and investigation has been the advantage of presenting the Tariff to Lyceum and Chautauqua audiences — composed of men, women and children. Long ago, from this most valuable experience, I learned that the thing most needed by the people in order to understand just what the Tariff is, how it works, and whom it benefits, is not Argument but Analysis — a division into classes of the persons and things affected at each step in the unfolding of the problem. The sole aim and purpose of the TARIFF PRIMER is to clarify and simplify the Tariff Issue. The method of working has been simply to analyze, and then classify in opposite groups, all the elements in each stage of the problem — taking them up carefully, just one at a time. A classification once made, or a principle once clearly established, is never abandoned. From the beginning to the end of the book I trust the reader will find that all the lines of reasoning run clear and straight. My endeavor has been to fully and logically tJiink out each problem for itself; seeking always to find the principle involved, using details and statistics only for illustration. Thus do we advance steadily from the first chapter to the last, following the definite plan of taking up and discussing just one thing at a time, always striving to so clearly and definitely state facts and conditions that the reader can think them out for himself — and find pleasure and entertainment in doing it. The cartoons and illustrations have been carefully designed in order to give the reader the imagery, the mental pictures, the concrete symbols, absolutely necessary for the mastery of the subject. Realizing that at least 80% of all our knowledge comes thru the eyes, an abundance of charts and diagrams has also been used, based wholly on Official Government Statistics. With all the vital questions and problems of the Tariff Issue clearly analyzed and definitely stated for the American people, this age-long superstition, this gigantic delusion that a people can be enriched by their own taxation, will go the way of all the other delusions and superstitions of the past. Mifilinburg, Pa. October 12, 1922. TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER I. Home Goods, Foreign Goods and the Tariff Wall 1 CHAPTER II. Motive that Builds Tariff Walls 4 CHAPTER III. The World Price Level and the TariflF Price Level 7 CHAPTER IV. Putting Foreign Goods Over the Tariff Wall ... 11 CHAPTER V. Price-Fixing Inside the Tariff Wall 13 CHAPTER VI. Monopolizing the Home Market 17 CHAPTER VII. How Much Is the Tariff Tax? 20 CHAPTER VIII. Where the Tariff Costs More Than the Goods 23 CHAPTER IX. Does the "Foreigner" Pay the Tariff? 25 CHAPTER X. Two Streams of Revenue 29 CHAPTER XI. The Higher the Rate— The Less the Revenue . . 32 CHAPTER XII. Who Gets It— Employees or Employers? 35 CHAPTER XIII. Does the Tariff Protect or Plunder Labor? 40 CHAPTER XIV. The Farmer and the Manufacturer 44 CHAPTER XV. The Farmer as an Exporter 49 CHAPTER XVI. Can the Farmers Form a Trust? 53 CHAPTER XVII. Does the Importation of Foreign Goods Throw Our Own Labor Out of Employment? 57 CHAPTER XVIII. Can We Import Without Exporting? 61 CHAPTER XIX. Our "Favorable" Balance of Trade 65 CHAPTER XX. My Two Islands 71 CHAPTER XXI. Revenue Tariffs vs. Protective Tariffs 79 APPENDIX A— Imports and Exports from 1790 to 1921 82 B — A Study in World Commerce 89 C— Effects of War on Prices 91 D— Price History from 1850 to 1920 93 E — Tariff Rates from Custom House Reports 95 F — 25 Leading Products Both Exported and Imported 96 G— Fordney Tariff at Work 96 H— Wool Prices from 1880 to 1921 96 I — Payne-Aldrich, Underwood and Fordney Tariffs 97 J— The Scramble Begins for Still Higher Rates 100 CHAPTER I. Home Goods, Foreign Goods and the Tariff Wall For untold centuries the word "foreign" has filled mankind with fear, because "foreigner" and "foe" meant the same thing. And the fear that there was some subtle danger, some hidden evil, even in "foreign goods" has continued through all the long and bloody centuries of war and hate and strife. This vague fear and indescribable dread of "foreign goods" still exists — and that, too, among so-called "civilized" nations. If this were not true. Protective Tariffs would have disappeared long ago with the other superstitions of the past. On the opposite page our artist has given us the three ele- ments essential to a complete discussion of the Tariff. In this picture we have the whole foundation of the subject. These three elements are: Home Goods, Foreign Goods, and the Tariff Wall between. _ Radical and far-reaching as is the distinction which all na- tions make between Home Goods and Foreign Goods, and pro- foundly as does this distinction effect the economic welfare and happiness of all mankind, yet the reader needs to realize at the very outset that it rests upon nothing more permanent and sub- stantial than national boundaries. On this boundary all Tariff Walls are built. National boundaries are wholly a matter of accident and chance, of whim and caprice, of war and treaty. As we learned in geography, national boundaries are not "natural" lines but "imaginary" lines drawn upon the surface of our earth. The 49th parallel of latitude forms the larger part of the boundary which separates us from Canada. All products coming in from beyond that parallel are "foreign", and if allowed to come in "free" it is supposed would destroy our great agricultural interests. By all means wheat from Alberta must be kept out. For twenty-four years has Mr. Porter J. McCumber been defending North Dakota from the disasters of such an "invasion". And yet the political slogan of an early Presidential cam- paign was: "54-40 or Fight!" They did not get either. But if the parallel of 54-40 had been established as our northern 2 TARIFF PRIMER boundary, the wheat fields of Alberta and of all northwestern Canada, would now pour their golden harvests into the gran- aries of Chicago and Minneapolis as freely as do the wheat fields of the Dakotas and Minnesota. What makes it injurious in the one case, but beneficial in the other? Merely the acci- dental location of a national boundary. Therefore, it is not the nature of the goods, or the character of the people producing them, but those "imaginary lines", called national boundaries, which divide all the products of human toil into Home Goods and Foreign Goods. We are not the only people who have a Tariff Wall, though from Protectionists' speeches in Congress, one would infer that this is our distinctive and exclusive creation. There are as many Tariff Walls on this planet as there are Governments. Canada, Mexico, the Republics of Central America and the countries of South America — all have Tariff Walls. Crossing the ocean. Tariff Walls and lines of fortification mark the bound- aries of all the countries of Europe. Every government on the continent of Africa is encircled by a Tariff Wall. The same is true of Asia, of the distant Orient, and of many of the islands of the sea. In short, wherever there is a Government on this earth there also is a Tariff Wall. Nor is that all. "We the people of the United States", now have but one Tariff Wall. But before the formation of the Federal Constitution in 1789, each of the thirteen colonies had a Tariff Wall around it. Connecticut, Massachusetts, New York, Pennsylvania, North Carolina — all had Tariff Walls. Wherever there was a boundary line separating two colonies, there also was a Tariff Wall. How history does persist in enacting over and over again its ancient follies! The same bickering and haggling and "log- rolling" which occupied the American Congress for nearly two years; also occupied the legislatures of the Colonies. Further- more, the same "arguments" which seek to justify the exist- ence of the one Tariff Wall around the entire Union of 48 states, would also justify the building of a Tariff Wall around each state. Therefore, if these "arguments" of Fordney, McCumber and their followers are true, then we should have 48 Tariff Walls instead of one! In Europe, a century or so ago, there was a Tariff Wall around each county, principality, dukedom, and feudal estate. It is said that a French peasant in going from Versailles to Paris with his cartload of garden products had to pass through eigh- Home Goods, Foreign Goods and the Tariff Wall 3 teen Tariff Walls, paying toll at each wall, before he reached the gates of Paris — and still had one more toll to pay before he could get inside the Tariff Wall around that city! And so the idea is not modern. It is centuries old. Senator Calder, of New York, recently claimed, before a labor audience, that the reason wages are higher in this country than in any other is because we have a Protective Tariff — im- plying, of course, that other countries have not. Nothing more ignorant or deceptive could possibly have been uttered. Whatever the reason, it is not this. Practically all countries on earth have a Protective Tariff. And statistics show that, as a general rule, the higher the Tariff the lower the wages of labor, and the more impoverished the people. Thus do Tariff Walls, separating Home Goods from Foreign Goods, exist everywhere — and have existed for centuries. They are as universal as greed; as persistent as Selfishness and Plunder. 4 TARIFF PRIMER CHAPTER II. MOTIVE THAT BUILDS TARIFF WALLS In the lowest stages of human society all the products which enter into the food, clothing and shelter of the people of the tribe are found within the narrow circuit of their own immedi- ate neighborhood. And nothing better indicates, the steps in the Intellectual Progress of the race than the ever increasing distance, over sea and land, from which their daily supplies are drawn. When we reach the highest civilization we find the articles consumed even by "the common people" are drawn from every country, zone and clime. Thus does the March of Progress, through the instrumen- tality of International Trade, enable the humblest citizen or subject in any nation to levy upon the vast variety of products of every sea and land, of every mountain range, valley and plain of the whole round earth, to satisfy the hunger and needs of his life — unless prevented by a Tariff Wall. Whoever would form a true mental picture of Trade must encompass the whole earth in his imagination. The compara- tively few whose intellectual development makes such a vision possible, believe in Trade. The unnumbered millions whose narrow and provincial minds make a conception of such mag- nitude impossible, believe in Tariff Walls. It is all a matter of imagination, of mental capacity — of Intellectual Development. Back of that towering Tariff Wall, in every nation — under every form of government — are two classes of people: The Producers of Home Goods and the Consumers of both Home and Foreign Goods. In this we have the Motive which in all lands and nations builds Tariff Walls. It is quite natural for local Producers everywhere to object to this intrusion of Foreign Goods into the Home Market. And the cause of this universal — and we might say interna- tional — objection of all local Producers to the importation of Foreign Goods is easy to discover. It is found in the fact that they must compete with these Foreign Goods in what they would like to consider their own exclusive market. And in order to compete they must keep their prices down to the prices of the Foreign Goods offered. Motive that Builds Tariff Walls 5 Otherwise, local consumers will naturally, and rightly, buy the Foreign Goods. From this vital fact comes a clear vision of the purpose, the motive, the function, of a Tariff Wall: THE OBJECT IN BUILD- ING A TARIFF WALL AROUND ANY COUNTRY IS TO ENABLE LOCAL PRODUCERS OF CERTAIN PRODUCTS TO COMPEL THE LOCAL CONSUMERS OF THESE PRODUCTS TO PAY MORE FOR THEM THAN THEY WOULD HAVE TO PAY IN THE OPEN MARKET. In other words, the Producer has carried his conflict with the Consumers of his products into the Halls of Congress. He has succeeded, by means of campaign contributions and other forms of "influence," in securing from Congress such laws- called Tariffs — as enable him to compel the consumers of his products to pay him more than they would otherwise have to pay — were it not for these laws. When we reflect on the matter, however, we see that there is no more reason — in fact, there is not as much reason — why the Producer should have a law compelling the Consumers to pay him more than the Market Price for his products, than that Consumers should have a law enacted by Congress which would compel Producers to sell their products for less than the Market Price. Had you ever thought of that? If not, then here is a chance to do some real thinking for yourself. You would not vote to build a Tariff Wall around your town, giving your merchants a monopoly of the Home Market; thus preventing you from going to any other town or city to buy any part of the necessities of life. Nor would you vote to build a Tariff Wall around your county, or even around your state. Since you demand an Open Market for the people of your town, an Open Market for the people of your county, and an Open Market for the people of your state, why do you not also demand an Open Market for the hundred and ten Million people of your nation? The World Price Level and the Tariff Price Level 7 CHAPTER III. THE WORLD PRICE LEVEL AND THE TARIFF PRICE LEVEL In the illustration on the opposite page, our artist has given us a symbol of the machinery which Congress has put into the hands of the Producer to enable him to get from the Consumer higher prices than the Consumer would have to pay in the open market. It shows how a Tariff Wall raises the PRICE LEVEL of the goods and products it "Protects." The illustration tells the whole story. Look it over and think it out for yourself. These billions of dollars' worth of Foreign Goods which every year we ourselves demand, need and consume, flow directly across the ocean to our shores down at the WORLD Price Level. There they are — down there. But we cannot get them — down there. Before we can reach them, or they reach us, they must flow up over the towering Tariff Wall — to the cost-plane of the TARIFF PRICE LEVEL. All goods shipped to us from any part of the world— Europe, Asia, Africa, Canada, South America, Mexico, Australia — must pass thru one of the scores of Custom Houses along the bound- ary separating us from the rest of the world, be inspected by custom house officials, and a Tariff Tax levied on them— unless specifically exempted by being on the Free List. Therefore, in each Custom House this Taxing Machinery must be set up and a separate Tariff Wall built for each class of articles, in order to compel us to purchase them — not at their normal price in the Open Market — but at the "Price In- creased by the Tariff." In order to thus systematically tax everything that labor has produced, our Tariff Makers — beginning as far back as 1883 — have divided all material substances and products which satisfy the desires and needs of human life into Fourteen Classes — called Schedules. There is absolutely no form of wealth which the genius of man has created, no product or invention which his skilled hands have fashioned, that does not fall within one of these Fourteen Schedules. A mere enumeration of their titles, to- gether with a few items under each, will give the reader some conception of the vast multitude of products in the huge stream of life's necessities, which it is now proposed shall be made to pass over "the highest Tariff Wall in our history." 8 TARIFF PRIMER (1) A— Chemicals, Oils and Paints: All forms of medi- cines and drugs, perfumes, floral waters, flavoring extracts, porous plaster, etc. (2) B— Earth, Earthenware and Glassware: All forms of bricks and clays, crushed limestone, watch crystals, tiles, china ware, Portland cement, mir- rors, plate glass, marble, spectacles, tombstones, etc. (3) C— Metals and Manufactures of Metals: Nuts, bolts and washers, nails, tacks and brads, corset steels, sewing machines, iron and aluminum ware, harness, saws, automobiles and parts, razors, watches, clocks, cutlery, etc. (4) D— Wood and Manufactures of: Furniture, porch and window blinds, picket pailings, toothpicks, butchers' skewers, casks, coffins, clothes pins, etc. (5) E— Sugar and Molasses: Cane sugar, beet sugar, maple sugar, syrups, candies and all other forms of confectionery. (6) F— Tobacco and Manufactures of: Wrapper and filler tobaccos, smoking tobacco, cigars, cigarettes, chewing tobacco, etc. (7) G— Agricultural Products and Provisions: Live stock, meat, fish, vegetables, milk and cream, but- ter, cereals, fruits, nuts, flours, bread, preserves, seeds, etc. (8) H— Spirits, Wines and Other Beverages: Brandy, cordials, malt extracts, soda water, mineral waters, cherry and fruit juices, etc. (9) I— Cotton and Manufactures of: Cotton staple, cotton yarns, sewing thread, tire fabrics, table covers, cotton gloves, cotton clothing, bedspreads, sheets and pillow cases, collars and cuffs, cotton cloth, cotton sheeting, pile fabrics, shoe strings, lace curtains, etc. (10) J— Jute, Hemp and Flax: Flax straw, fiber towels, bags and bagging, table damask, linoleum, floor oil- cloth, sheeting, straw mattings, etc. ( 11) K— Wool and Manufactures of: Wool and hair of sheep, goats, alpaca and like animals, wool yarn, blankets, robes, webbing, belts, hose, gloves, knit fabrics, underwear, all carpets and rugs, all clothing, wearing apparel, etc. The World Price Level and the Tariff Price Level 9 (12)L— Silk and Silk Goods: Sewing silk, plushes, velvets, ribbons, gloves, handkerchiefs, hosiery, underwear, all wearing apparel, all other silk manufactures. ( 13 )M— Paper and Books: Printing paper, letter paper, carbon paper, wall paper, paper board, wrapping paper, books of all kinds, leather-bound books, photograph albums, all other manufactures of paper, (14 )N— Sundries: Straw hats, tooth brushes, combs, all forms of buttons, all manufactures of leather, all embroideries and everything else not previously mentioned. Look about you in your home. There is scarcely a single article on which the eye can fall that does not bear a Tariff Tax. Even your sewing machine has been taken off the Free List and given a Tariff Tax. There is a Tariff Tax on practically every article of food on your table. This is true also of your dishes, silverware, cutlery, napkins and tablecloth ; as well as the table itself, the lighting fixtures above it, and the chairs upon which you sit. There is no article of clothing on your person down to the minutest detail which does not bear a Tariff Tax. The same is true of the house itself and of all the furnishings, ornaments, and kitchen utensils which it contains — from the cement in the foundation, the carpets on the floor, the paper and pictures on the wall, the glass in the windows, the curtains and shades, the tile in the fire-place, on up to the nails in the shingles on the roof — all bear a Tariff Tax. Some rhymester, with a keen sense of the humor and ab- surdity of the whole situation, has stated the case quite fully in poetic form: "We are taxed on our clothing, our meat and our bread, On our carpets and cupboard, our table and bed ; On our knives and our spoons, on our fuel and lights — We are taxed so severely we can't sleep o'nights. We are taxed on our hats, our shoes, and our shops. On our blankets and stoves, our brooms and our mops; On our rice and our sugar, and when we must die. We'll be taxed on the coffin in which we shall lie. We are taxed on all wants by Providence given. We are taxed on the Bible which points us to Heaven; And when we ascend to that heavenly goal, They will if they can, put a tax on our Soul." Putting Foreign Goods Over the Tariff Wall 11 CHAPTER IV. Putting Foreign Goods Over the Tariff Wall The picture on the opposite page gives us a "snap shot" of the importer of Foreign Goods in the act of shifting the Tariff Tax over on the American Consumer. The Tariff Tax of 100%, which we have assumed our Govern- ment had levied on his goods, has already been paid by the im- porter. He had to pay that before he could land his goods. The foreign cost of his goods, by the time he gets them to our shores, is assumed to be $400 per package. Our importer now has $800 capital invested in each package — $400 in the goods and $400 more in the tariff on the goods. Now what will he do? We know exactly what he will do. He will add the cost of the Tariff to the cost of the goods — making the price to us $800 instead of $400 — and shove the goods over the wall. He will also add tivo profits — one on the goods, and the other on the tariff. This process of shifting the cost of the tariff over on the Con- sumer holds to the last detail of the billions of dollars' worth of commodities which we annually import. In reference to each bill of goods, and each separate item imported, THE TARIFF Tax Levied by the Government Is Paid by the Mer- chant Who Brings the Goods Over— and by Him Is Added to the Cost of the Goods — and so is Paid by THE Consumer of the Goods. Thus do we see that it is not the importer, but the Consumer, who pays the Tariff. And on scores of articles, under the new Profiteers' Tariff, the cost of the tariff will be higher than the cost of the goods. But it will not be listed on our bill as a separate item — so much for the goods, so much for the tariff. If this were done, the inordinate rates in the Fordney-McCum- ber Tariff would not last a month without producing a revolu- tion. It is a secret, hidden mode of taxation. The people pay it without knowing that it is being paid. Fordney goes on Shakespeare's theory: "He who's robbed, but knows not of it, IS NOT ROBBED AT ALL." Price-Fixing Inside the Tariff Wall 13 CHAPTER V. Price-Fixing Inside the Tariff Wall Having shown that on the outside of our Tariff Wall the first act of those who bring over Foreign Goods is to add the cost of the tariff to the cost of the goods, our artist here shows us what is also taking place on the inside of the Tariff Wall. There- fore, no matter on which side of this towering structure you cast your gaze you behold the same little game — Adding THE Cost of the Tariff to the Cost of the Goods. The Only Object in Building a PROTECTIVE Tariff Wall Around This Country is to Increase the Price OF Foreign Goods to American Consumers, so that the American Producer Can Also Increase the Price of His Goods to these Same American Con- sumers. If it were not for the fact that High Tariffs, by increasing the price of Foreign Goods to American people, also make possible a parallel increase of price in the competing Home Goods, There Would Be No Protective Tariff Wall Around This Country, or Any Other Country. Now let us get an exact, scientific statement of the effects of High Tariffs on these two classes of goods. It is this: First, High Tariffs necessitate an increase in price of the Foreign Goods on which they are levied. Second, they make possible an increase of price on similar Home Goods which compete with them. They necessitate the one — they make possible the other. And it is for the sole purpose of making possible an increase in the selling price of Home Goods that all Protective Tariff Laws are passed. What other purpose could they have in levying such extor- tionate rates? They are not for the purpose of raising money for the Government. Low-rate Revenue Tariffs do that. Therefore, High Tariffs are levied solely for the purpose of raising revenue for private pockets. And to do this they must increase the price of Foreign Goods, thus making possible a parallel increase of price of the competing Home Goods. During the framing of a Tariff Bill, Washington is over-run with the lobbyists and representatives of the different "inter- 14 TARIFF PRIMER ests." They present to those in charge of the bill a statement showing the percentage rate of increase which they desire to make in the selling price of their products to their American Consumers — and which increase they insist they must have in order to continue to do business. And this BECOMES THE Tariff Rate on their Foreign Competitor's Goods. This gives us a broader and truer vision of the full signifi- cance of Protective Tariffs. We have already seen that the whole stream of Foreign Goods, amounting to some five billions annually, must go up over this towering Tariff Wall, with prices increased anywhere from 25% to 150%. Now we are called upon to form a still larger vision of that huge stream of Home Goods — more than ten times greater — which it is the purpose of the Fordney-McCumber Tariff to increase in cost to us Just the Same as if they also Flowed Over the Tariff Wall, Side by Side With Foreign Goods. The illustration at the head of the chapter might be thought to imply that all commodities can be produced in this country as cheaply as they can be produced abroad. Hence the reason for marking the whole of the increased price of Foreign Goods, necessitated by our High Tariff Wall, as simply so much addi- tional "profit" given to the Producers of similar Home Goods. On the other hand, our Tariff Makers have assumed just the reverse. They have assumed that we can produce absolutely nothing in this country as cheaply as it can be produced in foreign lands. The proof that this is their supposition is found in the fact that they have put tariff rates — and on thousands of articles high tariff rates — on practically everything that is pro- duced in this country — everything. Had you never thought of that? Thus would Mr. Fordney and his followers have us believe that with all our supposed skill, knowledge, education, machin- ery and inventive genius; that with all our schools, colleges and universities; even the most ignorant, degraded, illiterate and unskilled laborers on earth can produce anything cheaper — and therefore more efficiently — than our own laborers can produce it. And for that reason, undersell us in our own markets. Some tribute to American Labor! My answer is this: WHILE THERE ARE MANY COMMODI- TIES Which We Cannot Produce as Cheaply in This Country as They Can Be Produced Abroad, There Are Vastly More Commodities Which We Can Pro- duce, AND Do Produce, More Cheaply Than Any Price-Fixing Inside the Tariff Wall 15 Other Country in the World. Therefore, our artist's illustration is true as to principle, and holds as to detail in refer- ence to the big majority of all our productions. The proof of the above statement is found in the fact that we exported over $8,000,000,000 worth of goods during 1920. If we could not produce and undersell foreign competitors in their own market, they would not have bought these goods. But if we could undersell them in their own market — after paying the cost of transportation and the tariff in their country — surely we can undersell them here. No sane man will deny that. A profound analysis thus enables us to divide all our produc- tions into two distinct classes: (1) Those which we can pro- duce more cheaply than we can buy from abroad. (2) Those which we cannot produce as cheaply as we can buy them; and, therefore, which we cannot produce at all without the aid of a Protective Tariff. The question in reference to the first class of productions can have but one answer: THE ADDED PRICE WHICH THE Tariff Makes it Possible for Their Producers to Get from Us Is Simply a Bounty, a Bonus. It is tribute, graft, plunder — extortion. No man or woman with any intel- lectual pride will deny that proposition. But what shall we say of that second class of goods and pro- ducts which I myself claim, or admit, can jiot be produced in this country without the aid of a Protective Tariff? To this also there can be but one answer: ANY LINE OF GOODS OR Products Which Cannot Be Produced in This Coun- try Without the Aid of a Protective Tariff — Ought Not to Be Produced At All. And that for the reason that all such goods and products are produced at an absolute economic and financial loss to the country. To illustrate, the same amount of labor expended in Louis- iana in producing corn, cotton or any other "native" product, and traded for sugar, would give far more sugar than it now gives by producing sugar direct. Thus by means of Protect- ive Tariffs we are diverting labor to the least productive sources, instead of employing it in the most productive sources. This unfortunate experiment of trying to produce a Tropical plant in the Temperate Zone has been an economic loss of billions of dollars to the American people. And in the new Tariff the stage is again set for the Sugar Trust to collect hundreds of millions more. Monopolizing the Home Market 17 CHAPTER VI. Monopolizing the Home Market In the picture on the opposite page our artist has given us a new situation, one in which the American Producer does not increase the cost of his goods to the full extent that the Tariff has increased the cost of his foreign competitor's goods. In doing this he shows us how the American Producer, by getting a Tariff Wall high enough, can make huge profits and still undersell his foreign competitor — and thus establish a monopoly of the Home Market for his own products. In the last picture we saw the American Producer marking up the price of his goods to Consumers to an equality in price with his foreign competitor's goods, thus placing Home Goods up on the Tariff Price Level side by side with Foreign Goods. In the present illustration he takes just the opposite course. These two drawings graphically picture to us the two possible alternatives, which a Tariff Wall presents to favored Producers in every country. In the first alternative, prices of Home Goods are boosted clear to the top of the wall. While by this course they will supply only a part of the local demand — the rest being supplied v/ith Foreign Goods — THEY WILL GET More for What They Do Sell. The second alternative is that of taking advantage of only a part of the increase of price which a High Tariff makes pos- sible. In the illustration, the Tariff Wall raised the price of a given foreign product from $400 to $800. The American Pro- ducer, by raising his price to only $700, keeps the Foreign Goods out, and establishes a monopoly of the Home Market. WHILE Making a Less Profit on Each Individual sale, yet he has the supplying of the entire home demand for himself. Even for the lower prices at which manufacturers must sell their products in the Home Market, in order to "corner" this market, THEY HAVE A REMEDY, and a good one. This ex- plains the terrific and disgraceful scramble at Washington dur- ing the pending of a Tariff Bill to secure high rates. The instructions of the Big Interests to the representatives they are sending to Washington during the framing of a Tariff Bill is to this effect: "Get the tariff high enough on our for- 18 TARIFF PRIMER eign competitor's goods. Make sure of that. Then we can raise prices as high as the people can possibly pay, and still hold a monopoly of the Home Market." Therefore, even tho selling under the foreign price increased by the Tariff, they can still get from the people "All THAT the Traffic Will Bear." It makes no difference to us, the Consumers, which course is taken. Either one permits the forming of Trusts and Com- bines. In order to raise the price of Home Goods up to the cost of Foreign Goods on the Tariff Price Level, combinations and "gentlemen's agi'eements" must be made to prevent com- petition among themselves — and thus keep prices up. NO Tariff Wall Can Long Benefit Any Industry With- out THE Aid of Trusts and Monopolies. Therefore, if the Producers of any "protected" product are unable to "get-together" and form Trusts and Combines — as is particularly true of the millions engaged in agriculture— then local competition among themselves will hold the price of their product down to the same general level that would exist IF There Were No Tariff Wall. Thus are Tariffs and Trusts inseparable. The Tariff makes the Trust possible — the Trust makes the Tariff useful. Mr. Fordney has asserted, over and over again, that he is not seeking to establish a Monopolistic Tariff, but a Competi- tive Tariff. In saying this Mr. Fordney shows himself to be either an ignoramus in economics or a demagog. The reader may choose whichever term seems the more charitable. Why do I say this? Because to make a Tariff Bill "competi- tive" — with average rates of between 60% and 70% — depends not on Mr. Fordney, but on American Producers taking full advantage of the 'price- fixing opportunities which he has so liberally given them; by so marking up the price of their goods as to place them on an equality with Foreign Goods at the Tariff Price Level. Then the cost of either will be exactly the same to us. That alone would make a "competitive" Tariff. However, if that were done, two very surprising things would happen. First, not only will FOREIGN GOODS be in- creased to us the full extent of the tariff rates on them, but the volume of HOME GOODS, ten times greater, will also be in- creased in cost to us the full extent that the Tariff Wall in- creased the cost of Foreign Goods. And the higher the tariff rates, the higher will be the price of Home Goods. Some con- tribution to old H. C. L. Monopolizing the Home Market 19 And yet Fordney, McCumber and their followers have re- peatedly claimed that their tariff WILL NOT INCREASE THE Cost of Home Goods. Let us see if it would not. To make it a "competitive" tariff Foreign Goods must come in. That much is certain. But they cannot come in unless Home Goods are marked up to an equality of price with them; so that whether we buy Foreign Goods or Home Goods, we must get both up on the Tariff Price Level — at the same cost to us. Therefore, The Only Way Normal Competition Can be Re- stored Between Us and Foreign Countries, Under the Monstrous and "Unconscionable" Rates in the fordney-mccumber tariff, is to enormously in- CREASE THE Costs of All Domestic Products to the American People. In the second place, if Mr. Fordney's Tariff is what he claims it is — a Competitive Tariff — Foreign Goods would still come in. But he also claims that foreign importations THROW AMERI- CAN Labor Out of Employment. If this Tariff allows Foreign Goods to come in, which it must do in order to be a Competitive Tariff, instead of a Prohibitive Tariff, then it will also throw labor out of employment just the same as he claimed the Underwood Tariff did. The only difference would be that under his Tariff labor will have to pay far more for the necessi- ties of life than it did under the Underwood Tariff. So labor will gain nothing in the way of employment, but will lose tre- mendously by having to pay vastly more for the necessities of life! 20 TARIFF PRIMER CHAPTER VII. How Much is the Tariff Tax? Your state and county tax runs only so many mills on the dollar for each different item. When it gets as high as three cents on the dollar you begin to protest. You know there is extravagance somewhere. Three cents on the dollar is only 3%. The Tariff Tax on any article is seldom less than 25%. That is eight times as much. In many cases your Tariff Tax is twenty-five times as much as your state and county tax. Think of it. And yet you grumble at the one, but are in favor of the other. You know that the one is a burden. But some- how you have the idea that a TAX TWENTY-FIVE TIMES Greater Is a Blessing! While the tariff rate usually begins at 25%, it does not end there. It goes to 35%, 50%, 60%, 80%, 100%. It goes even beyond this to 125%, and on up to 200% — and more. The Payne-Aldrich Tariff of 1909 had an average rate on all articles of about 60%. Before his death, Senator Penrose, then Chair- man of the Senate Finance Committee, is reported to have said that some of the rates in the Fordney Tariff Bill, which had just passed the House, would go as high as 800%. There are two classes of Tariff duties: Specific and Ad Val- orum. The latter means "according to value." For instance, the McKinley Tariff of 1890 levied an ad valorum duty of 50% on women's and children's dress goods, 60% on ready-made clothing and wearing apparel, 60% on webbings, beltings and ribbons. On Ambussen, Saxony and Brussels carpets, 40%. On woolen cloths— worth more than 40c per pound — 50%. Nearly all of these rates were continued by the Dingley and the Payne-Aldrich Tariffs, and now by the Fordney-McCumber Tariff. A Specific Duty is levied, not "according to value", but ac- cording to quantify. For instance, the Tariff of 1872 laid a specific duty of $28 per ton on steel rails! On the articles above mentioned, the McKinley Tariff laid a specific duty of 12c a yard on women's and children's dress goods, 50c a pound on ready-made clothing, 60c a pound on webbings, beltings and ribbons, 60c a square yard on Ambusson and Saxony car- How Much Is the Tariff Tax? 21 pets, 44c per square yard on Brussels carpet and 44c a square yard on all woolen cloths worth over 40c a pound. Both duties are used on hundreds of articles. When so used they are called Compound Duties. In the McKinley Tariff, the Compound Duties on women's and children's dress goods, gave a total tariff rate of 104%; on ready-made clothing and wearing apparel, 80%; on webbings, beltings, ribbons, etc., 94%; on Ambusson and Saxony carpets, 69%; on Brussels car- pets, 81% ; and on woolen cloth mentioned above, 143%. These rates were largely preserved in the Dingley Tariff of 1897 and most of them were increased in the Payne-Aldrich Tariff of 1909, while the rates in the latter tariff have been perpetuated, and many of them increased, by the Fordney-McCumber Tariff. As showing still further the effects of compound duties, the McKinley Tariff imposed a total duty of 112% on cheap woolen yarns, 108% on cheap woolen blankets, 130% on worsted goods, 138% on cheap knit goods, and on the lowest grade of pearl buttons, 280%. The effect of compound duties is to put the highest tariff rates on the cheapest goods, thus throwing the great burden of Tariff Taxation on the toiling masses of any country. The ex- planation is clear. For instance, if the ingrain carpets, with a specific duty of 22c per square yard, have a foreign value of only 22c per square yard, then the poorer classes who must buy the cheaper grades would be paying a hundred per cent, on the specific duty alone. To this was added a 40% ad valorum duty. It is estimated that the specific duty of 31c per pound in the Fordney-McCumber Tariff on scoured wool, will make a tariff rate of 137% on some of the cheaper grades of wool. Before the war our total dye bill was $15,000,000. That is, we used only $15,000,000 worth of dye each year in this country. When the importations of dye from Germany were stopped, we started to manufacture our own dyes, and the Dye Interests in this country made $150,000,000 profit on four dyes alone in six years. In other words, their profit on four dyes in six years was ten times our yearly dye bill before the war. The multi- millionaires back of the Dye Monopoly, fought for two years to secure an absolute embargo. They failed in this, but got a Compound Duty of 7 cents a pound, plus 60% — American Valuation — which practically amounts to an embargo. Noth- ing in the "Tariff' of Abomination" of 1829 can compare to that. There is but little hope for the future of a people who would tolerate such an outrage on human rights! 22 TARIFF PRIMER To be brief, the Fordney-McCumber Tariff has perpetuated, and increased, the extortionate rates of the McKinley Tariff and of the Payne-Aldrich, both of which were overwhelmingly defeated at the polls in the first elections which followed. It is estimated that the Fordney Tariff will enable the Big Interests to take out of the pockets of the people of one single state— New York— a tribute amounting to $330,000,000! In the New York World of September 22, the day following the signing by President Harding of the Fordney-McCumber Tariff, I find a very compact summing up of the total cost to the American people of the new Tariff Tax. The article is as follows: "WASHINGTON, Sept. 21. — Every American family will pay an average of $160 a year more for clothes, food and other necessities because of the Fordney-McCumber Tariff bill. Treasury experts said today. Although the total cost of living will be increased by $4, 000,000, 000, the bill carries a new provision authorizing the President to increase the rates 50%. if he desires. Of the total protection of $6,500,000,000, only $230,000,000 will be paid into the Treasury and the rest will go to the favored interests, according to the experts. The following is the estimated amount of protection on principal products: Cement, pottery, chinaware, $214,000,000; steel and other metals, $1,- 148,000,000; wood, furniture, lumber, $297,000,000; sugar, confectionery, $333,000,000; tobacco, $429,000,000; food, agricultural products, $1,233,- 000,000; cotton goods, $807,000,000; wool clothing, $760,000,000; silk and silk goods, $326,000,000." The consensus of opinion, to sum it all up, is that the Ford- ney-McCumber Tariff will increase the cost of life's necessities to the American people about $4,000,000,000 annually. Thus do we hope to enrich ourselves by our own taxation — and by the most elaborate, detailed and burdensome system of taxation the world has ever known. How such a hope should have gotten possession of the brain of an enlightened people is beyond human comprehension. Other people have fought and died to prevent taxation. We fight to obtain it. Other people have declared it life's greatest burden. We regard it as the richest of blessings. Other people have risen in insurrection to prevent the tax rate from being raised. We express fear and alarm at the mere prospect of the Tariff Tax being lowered. Where the Tariff Costs More than the Goods 23 CHAPTER VIII. Where the Tariff Costs More Than the Goods The reader is probably astounded at the suggestion repeat- edly made that on scores of articles the tariff costs more than the goods; hence that MORE THAN HALF OF THE CON- SUMER'S Money Goes, Not for the Goods, But for THE Tariff on the Goods. The custom house records of the past fifty years are strewn with such illustrations. I shall select only a few from a volume issued by the Government entitled "Imports and Duties, 1894- 1907," page 889. I shall give the number of the table in which the reader will find the facts and figures as here set down. If facts can convince you then you are going to be convinced. YARNS, MADE WHOLLY OR IN FART OF WOOL (Act of 1897) Table No. 3562.- -Value not more than 30 cents per pound. Year Foreign cost Cost of tariff Total cost to Rate of tariff of goods on goods Consumer Tax 1898 $1,962.30 $2,803.10 $4,765.40 142% 1899 997.30 1,770.87 2,768.17 177% 1900 206.78 352.07 558.85 170% Table No. 3563, . — Value more than 30 cents per pound. 1898 $ 89,004.10 $ 93,040.84 $182,044.94 104% 1899 128,296.06 131,292.96 259,589.02 102% CLOTHS, WOOLEN OR WORSTED Table No. 3588. , — Value more than 30 cents per pound 1894 $3,323.00 $5,345.63 $8,608.63 161% 1895 3,870.00 6,384.81 10,254.81 165% Table No. 3589. — Value more than 30 cents and not more than 40 cents per pound 1894 $66,775.00 $97,312.01 $164,087.01 146% 1895 23,530.00 35,794.51 59,324.51 152% DRESS GOODS, WOMEN'S AND CHILDREN'S LININGS, ETC. Table No. 3612. — Value not more than 40 cents per pound $2,268.59 $3,688.59 159% 1,640.62 2,754.62 149% 579.67 947.67 157% 444.35 709.35 167% 1898 $1,420.00 1902 1,094.00 1905 368.00 1906 265.00 24 TARIFF PRIMER PLUSHES AND OTHER PILE FABRICS Table No. 3641. — Value not more than 40 cents per pound Year Foreign cost Cost of tariff Total cost to Rate of tariff of goods on goods Consumer Tax 1898 $ 89.00 $162.64 $251.64 183% BLANKETS Table No. 3571. — Value not more than 40 cents per pound 1903 $ 371.00 $ 677.86 $1,048.86 183% 1904 1,016.00 1,447.51 2,463.51 142% 1905 507.00 807.74 1,314.74 159% 1906 561.50 1,013.68 1,575.18 180% Enough has been given to show at least the basis of the con- clusion which every honest and enlightened thinker must reach in reference to "protection," and that conclusion is that it is THE MOST COLOSSAL AND OPPRESSIVE SCHEME OF PLUNDER WHICH THE GREED, CUPIDITY AND BRUTE SELFISHNESS OF MAN EVER CONCEIVED. It has taken its millions and hundreds of millions out of the pockets of those whose poverty compels them to purchase the cheapest quality of goods. This is one of the mighty reasons why the millions are poor. They have been plundered into poverty by a long line of thieving Tariffs. You will observe, for example, that in "ya-rns, made wholly or in part of wool," the tariff rates on those having a value of 30 cents, or less, go as high as 177%; while those having a value of over 30 cents a pound, have tariff rates of only 104%. The 104% is paid by those in comfortable circumstances, while the 177% Tariff Tax is paid by the poorest of our poor. This scheme of putting the highest Tariff on the cheapest goods will apply to the Fordney-McCumber Bill the same as it did to the McKinley, the Dingley and the Payne- Aldrich. I can see how such an economic policy could, and does, plunder, impoverish and despoil the multiplied millions of our own countrymen who must consume the cheaper grades of goods. But I cannot see how it can enrich them. I cannot see how it can lessen their burden of toil by increasing the cost of their necessities of life. Can you? Any policy which makes it possible, even in a single instance, to take from the toiling m.asses MORE THAN HALF of what they expend for the necessities of life to pay the Tariff on these necessities, deserves the righteous wrath and condemnation of any so-called "free" people. If it really be true that people are "prospered" by being plundered, then great should be the prosperity of the toiling multitudes of America! Does the ''Foreigner'' Pay the Tariff? 25 CHAPTER IX. Does the "Foreigner" Pay the Tariff? For generations Protectionists have used as one of their vital arguments to defend their acts in increasing the cost of the necessities of life that "THE FOREIGNER PAYS THE TARIFF". When the people would protest against exorbitant tariff rates, the answer was, "What does it matter to you? The foreigner pays the tax." Nor did this baseless subterfuge originate in this country. It was used in England long before the "Repeal of the Corn Laws" in 1846, and is still employed by Protec- tionists in Europe. The suggestion that "The foreigner pays the tax" has a deeper significance even than appears on the surface. It is a vague suggestion that the people of one country, by means of the Tariff, can tax the people of another country; and thus compel them to pay the expense of the government of the people levying the Tariff. The idea dates back to foreign wars and conquests. It is the old thirst to tax and plunder "foreign" nations. For example. Senator McCumber gave this as his excuse for levying a preposterous rate on some product: "We have taxed the people all they can pay with our income tax, corpora- tion tax, etc. We still need more revenue. And so I thought I would collect the extra amount needed at the custom house." The implication being that these "extra millions" would not come out of our pockets, but out of the pockets of the "for- eigners." This belief is universal. When a college student at Al• 5^ ■a' 4P o en CO CO 4? •o <_) •< to 5? O Ci HP* ^ r- Ci Go o tS o o v3 o 6 Q UJ -J O h ^ o *> .^ u i2 55: !2 5~ ^ t- 5«^ Cv v3 12 3~ ^ :r- o Q. Uj 2 o CO / U ^ Oq ^ ey- es of X Z) Q t^ be bo V9 ^ io ^ 1 (X. l> c^ C9 !>. to — 1 o CL u CO ■3- CO CO CO 5 ^ 5^ CO^ CO d o o o ^ ^ w v^ ^ ^ ■J ? cV ^ W -J — <^ lO sfl t> u o ZH c>/ fO :t- ^ «>- bo cr 6 The Farmer As an Exporter 49 CHAPTER XV. The Farmer as an Exporter On the opposite page is a table showing the simultaneous rise and fall of the price of wheat in Chicago, Minneapolis, Duluth, Winnipeg, Toledo, Kansas City and Liverpool. The relative prices are given for the first twenty days of July, 1922. The figures were furnished me by the Produce Exchange of New York. The Liverpool prices are made according to the rate of exchange for each day, and so are exact. Study this table, think out its meaning, and you will know vastly more about the Law of the Market Price than you ever conceived of before. I submit it to the thought and intelligence of my readers without further comment. And in this we have the proper atmosphere for the opening of this chapter. There are two general reasons why even the highest Pro- tective Tariff cannot increase the price of things the farmer has to sell to the same extent that it increases the price of the manu- factured products he has to buy — even if it increases them at all. In fact, there are two general reasons why it will not in- crease the selling price of his products. The first is the undeniable fact that our farmers, as a class, are our greatest exporters, producing nearly one-half of our total exports to foreign lands. Therefore, they must sell in the Open Market of the world, with prices fixed at Liverpool, England, an international market — the international market of the world for farm products. They must sell in competition with the farm products of all the nations of the earth. No Tariff Wall can keep their competitors out of that market. IT Is THE Price of Farm Products in that Interna- tional Market Which Determines their Price in Our Own Market. Our total exports for 1920 were $8,080,480,821. This is the largest aggregation of exports sent out from its shores by any country on earth. Of these exports the products of the farm alone amounted to $3,230,101,784. This is approximately 40% of the total. If to this we add the raw materials which go directly into manufactured products for export, and the price of which in the international market necessarily react on the 50 TARIFF PRIMER price of the farm products at home, we then would have over half of our exports supplied by our agricultural population. Of breadstuffs alone we exported $1,079,107,701. The fol- lowing table shows something of the farmer's stake abroad. IMPORTS EXPORTS Barley (none) $ 27,165.189 Corn $ 9,296,991 26,543,681 Cotton 138,743,702 1,136,408,916 Eggs 617,909 13,569,144 Meat and Dairy Products 64,274,457 544,074,060 Oats 6,549,111 12,338,104 Oat Meal & Rolled Oats (none) 3,891,346 Rice 14,085,728 37,469,175 Rye (none) 122,239,537 Tar, Pitch & Turpentine (none) 34,503,389 Tobacco 81,630,011 245,532,069 Wheat 75,359,220 596,975,396 Wheat-Flour 3,669,300 224,472,448 It was said over and over again by Mr. Fordney and his fol- lowers that they propose to protect and defend the American farmer in his Home Market and shield him from the "dumping" of the farm products of the world into his Home Market. From all this we would infer that the farmers of all the rest of the earth are eager for the chance to pounce upon our markets and "unload "their wheat, corn, oats and flour on us. In alarm- ing tones they tell us that with the very first opportunity given, the farmers of other countries would so completely "flood" our markets as to supply all our wants in food products, and in all other products now furnished us by our own farmers — thus leaving our own farmers without a market! Since 1913, however, there has been a very low tariff rate even on the "protected" products of the farm, under the Under- wood Tariff; while wheat, flour, com, hogs, cattle, bacon and ham have been on the Free List — no tariff on them at all. Here, then was their opportunity. For eight years our ports were wide open for the farm products of the world to come in and "flood" our markets. Did they come in? Did those crushing and appalling things happen which Messrs. Fordney and McCumber said would happen? They did not. Suppose that the thing they prophesied had actually happened, suppose that the whole of the Canadian export, instead of going to Liver- pool, had been unloaded on the mills at Minneapolis and else- where, and ground into flour by American labor. Would anything serious have resulted in the price of Ameri- can wheat? Nothing that any rational mind can picture. The Farmer As an Exporter 51 Why? Because the Liverpool price is always higher than our own market price. The more of our wheat which Canadian wheat "displaced" at Minneapolis, the more wheat we could have exported to Liverpool, at the higher price. Over there is an unlimited demand. For instance, our combined exports of wheat for 1919 and 1920 was greater than the total Canadian production of wheat. We exported in those two years, 507,- 266,128 bushels. Canada's total production for those two years was only 456,449,700 bushels. Our total production for those two years was 1,855,703,000 bushels. With that Liverpool market calling loudly for the excess pro- ductions of both countries, what does it matter as to whether Canada ships her wheat to Liverpool, and so "displaces" so much of our wheat there, or ships it to Minneapolis, thus re- leasing so much more of our wheat for the Liverpool market, averaging a dollar a bushel more than is paid at Minneapolis. We must remember also that the imports and exports in 1920 occurred under this same so-called "free trade" Underwood Tariff, and before the farmers Emergency Tariff was enacted. Furthermore, since its enactment, no man can furnish any valid evidence to show that it raised the general level of the price of farm products one single penny. The builders of the Fordney-McCumber Tariff Wall would have us believe that this is the first time that "protection" has been given to the products of the farm. The truth is, as stated be- fore, that the protection of farm products began as far back as 1883. On wheat it put a tariff rate of 20 cents a bushel. The Mc- Kinley Tariff reduced it to 15 cents, the Cleveland Tariff raised it to 20 cents, the Dingley increased it to 25 cents, and the Payne- Aldrich Tariff continued this rate. The Underwood Tariff put wheat and a few other farm pro- ducts on the Free List. And yet the excess of farm exports over imports continued in approximately the same proportion as when they were under High Tariffs. Nor is that all. The prices of farm products, like the wages of labor, were higher under the Underwood Revenue Tariff than ever before in our history. There can be but one conclusion, and that conclusion is that the American Farmer, like the American Laborer, sells his pro- duct in an Open Market and buys back the necessities of life in a Closed Market — sells under Free Trade: buys under Pro- tection. If that would not impoverish and bankrupt any class of people on earth, I would like to know what would. Can the Farmers Form a Trust? 53 CHAPTER XVI. Can the Farmers Form a Trust? In reply to the undeniable fact that the American farmer produces an excess of products over the requirements of the Home Market, and is an exporter, it may be said that, among other manufacturers, the United States Steel Corporation is also an exporter, selling its product in every country on earth. Quite true. But this gigantic corporation is a Trust. And back of it also is a monopoly of the raw materials in the earth from which all iron and steel are made. It is the largest Indus- trial Combine on earth, overshadowing even the Federal Gov- ernment at Washington. Hence it is in position to take full advantage of a Tariff Wall. It is the fact of its being a Trust which enables it to sell in the Home Market — to the farmers and the rest of us — at monopolistic prices, and then to sell to the people of other nations at the Open Market price — often at only about half of what is charged here for the same thing. Charles M. Schwab once admitted that when steel rails were selling in this country at $28 a ton, they were selling in Europe at $20 a ton. And the same fact holds of scores of "protected" products. THEY Are Sold Cheaper Abroad Than at Home. This is the impregnable position of that huge Industrial Octopus, called Monopoly, which our artist has sketched for us on the opposite page. The Tariff shields him from foreign competition, the Trust shields him from home competition — and his Monopoly is complete. But the farmers of this country, whether for good or ill, can- not form a Trust. They are too numerous. And they are too poor. The railroad and the Trust have seen to that. THEY Compete With Each Other. This competition they can- not prevent. Manufacturers and mine monopolists can pre- vent competition among themselves by forming Trusts — and thus are able to keep prices up and take full advantage of the "protection" given them. So far as a general statement can be made as to the law deter- mining which Producers can be benefited by High Tariffs and which cannot, it would seem to be this: Only Those Pro- Can the Farmers Form a Trust? 55 DUCERS OF Wealth Who Are Able to so Combine Their Interests As to Form Pools, Trusts and Gen- tlemen's Agreements— Thus Preventing Competi- tion Among Themselves— Can Be Benefited to Any Appreciable Extent By a Protective Tariff. Thus are Trusts and Monopolies indispensable to Producers in order to get the whole of that increased cost of Home Goods which the Tariff on Foreign Goods makes possible. But the farmers cannot form a Trust and so cannot be benefited to any appreciable extent — if at all — by High Tariffs. But while Protective Tariffs cannot possibly be of any general benefit to our farming population, they can be, and have been, the cause of Tremendous Detriment and Financial Loss to Them. Practically all economists are in absolute agreement on that point. They are a detriment to the farmer in two ways: First, the Tariff always has increased, and always will increase, the cost of the manufactured products he has to buy far more than it will increase the price of the things he has to sell — even assuming that it does increase them at all. That makes a continuous financial drain on the farming population of hundreds of mill- ions annually. It has been going on for decades and genera- tions, and has taken its billions out of the pockets of the Ameri- can farmer. Therefore, when the Underwood Revenue Tariff put wheat, wool and other farm products, on the Free List, it took abso- lutely nothing from the farmer — except the delusion that he was being prospered by the very thing that was plundering him! On the other hand, when the Underwood Revenue Tariff put agricultural machinery, binder twine, cotton bagging, oils and scores of other products on the Free List, and cut in half the tariff rates on woolen goods, cotton goods, clothing, women's and children's dress goods, and all the other things the farmer must buy. It Gave the Farmer the First Beneficial Legisla- tion He Has Had In Years. There is a second way in which a Protective Tariff is a detri- ment to American farmers. No people, producing an excess of farm products, can export them, unless the imports coming back are largely the products of the factory. That is, in order for them to buy our farm products they must be able to sell us the products of their factories. The illustration on the opposite page speaks volumes both to the millions of our farming population and to the millions more 56 TARIFF PRIMER working on salary and wages in the towns and cities of the na- tion. Look it over. Think it out for yourself. It means low wages, tragic decline in price of farm products, industrial stag- nation and bankruptcy. And just to the extent that the new Tariff Wall obstructs our trade with the world, it will produce these effects. In other words. To THE EXTENT THAT THE fordney-mccumber tariff keeps foreign goods Out It Will Keep Home Goods In. Therefore, when tariff rates on manufactured products are so high as to be prohibitive — which they are on scores of articles under the Fordney-McCumber Tariff — and so keep Foreign Goods out, then the hundreds of millions in Foreign Lands can- not buy from our farmers; because they cannot export their own products to pay for them — when a Tariff Wall keeps them out. This is exactly what happened in 1919. Europe was un- able to buy our farm products even though her millions were starving — because they had nothing to give in exchange. The result was that our farmers had to dump their enormous surplus into their own home markets — and the bottom dropped out. We barely escaped the greatest industrial crash in our history. It is now proposed by means of an artificial barrier, known as the Fordney-McCumber Tariff, To Do EXACTLY THE SAME Thing. They have the goods to send in but the Tariff Wall is designed to keep them out. The American farmer has yet to realize the great economic truth that THE SAME TARIFF Wall Which Keeps Foreign Goods Out Keeps Home Goods In. When at length the light breaks, the American farmer will feel the stir of the Heroic Spirit of '76, and will declare that since he cannot be benefited by a Tariff Wall around his pro- duct, neither shall the manufacturer of the East be further en- riched by a Tariff Wall; that since he must sell his products in the Open Market of the World in competition with the products of all lands and nations, so likewise shall the American manu- facturer sell to him in the Open Market, and in competition with the Goods and Products of all other lands and nations. Then, and not till then, will come a new order of things for the American Farmer. Does the hnportation of Foreign Goods, Etc. 57 CHAPTER XVII. Does the Importation of Foreign Goods Throw Our Own Labor Out of Employment? That question goes to the very heart of the whole Tariff issue. Everywhere there exists a positive fear and dread, amounting to actual terror, at the very thought of having large quantities of Foreign Goods brought into the country. It is a universal fear — a universal delusion. Furthermore, you get exactly the same reason for this fear in China or Germany, Russia or Italy, France or Mexico, Canada or the United States. The ancient fear of the invasion of foreign armies has been transferred to the fear and terror of an "invasion" of foreign goods. This belief is based on the supposition that there is a direct conflict, a positive antagonism, between Importing and Pro- ducing — a conflict so direct that when either goes up the other must of necessity go down: the more goods you produce in your own country, the less you will import from foreign coun- tries — the more you import from foreign countries, the less you will produce at home. In other words, to the extent that any people import they will not produce. The basis of this world-wide superstition that the importation of Foreign Goods throws home labor out of employment seems perfectly reasonable, provided you see only immediate results and are incapable of thinking back to see what is necessary, absolutely necessary, in order that you can import Foreign Goods. Or if you assume that we should produce everything we consume— No MATTER HOW GREAT THE ECONOMIC Loss IN Doing It — then the conclusion will seem perfectly valid to you. In other words, it requires but little intelligence to believe that foreign importations throw our own labor out of employ- ment. But it does require complex thinking to be able to see that it does 7wt throw home labor out of employment, but gives employment to home labor instead. And yet that is the conclusion which a high order of intelligence must reach. The primary facts in the case are undisputed. For example, if you buy all your shoes abroad you will not patronize our own makers of shoes. If you buy all your clothing abroad — that 58 TARIFF PRIMER is, from foreign producers — you will not give employment to the factory workers in our own mills. In short, if you buy everything abroad then you will buy nothing at home. That much is certain. But even if you did all this, and if every man, woman and child in America did likewise — a thing impossible — would this diminish the amount of wealth actually produced in this coun- try? Most certainly not. Would the buying abroad of abso- lutely everything we consume throw our own laborers out of em- ployment? Not a single laborer. On the contrary, if this impossible thing were done according to the Laws of Trade — namely, To BUY WHERE You Can Buy the Cheapest, AND Sell Where You Can Sell the Dearest— it would increase both the volume of our annual production of wealth And the Wages of American Labor. What, then, is the source of the delusion that the importation of Foreign Goods diminishes by so much the production of Home Goods, and so throws labor out of employment? It arises, primarily, from the use of the word "buy". There is no such thing as buying. We do not "buy" Foreign Goods. We trade for them. Foreign peoples do not "buy" from us. They trade with us — exchanging goods for goods. They can get our goods in no other way. And the only possible way that we can get their goods is to trade our goods for them. In fact, there really is no such thing as Buying and Sell- ing even among ourselves. In the ultimate analysis, what takes place is not buying but trading. Always and every- where what we call buying and selling, consists in the exchange of service for service. Money merely facilitates the exchange of these services. But trade does not eliminate production among ourselves. We still must produce something, or render some service, to exchange for the money with which we "buy." And the same principle holds of our consumption of Foreign Goods. And yet the old delusion continues and is the basis of the whole superstition of Protection. For example. Congressman Gernard of Pennsylvania, speak- ing in the House, July 14, 1921, said: "We dare not be deceived with the thought that America can open wide her gates to the markets of the world without destroying and endangering her own industrial health." Congressman Graham of Illinois, later, said : "Imports were flooding in to us from across the seas, TAK- ING the Place of the manufactured articles which hereto- fore our higher salaried American workmen had been making." Does the Importation of Foreign Goods, Etc. 59 Senator Smoot of Utah gave one of the clearest statements of this colossal superstition, this gigantic delusion, that I have ever seen. On May 20, 1914, he said: "Every dollar of im- portation Takes the Place of a dollar's worth of goods manufactured in this country." Now let us face the facts. Is it true that importations take the place of production at home? Is it true that the one is a substitute for the other? Members of Congress never tire in talking about what they call the "free trade" Cleveland Tariff, and the awful flood of Foreign Goods that was dumped on our shores. But I find that under the McKinley Tariff, 1892, '93, '94— we imported $72,- 372,955 more goods than we did in the three years under the Cleveland Tariff— 1895, '96, '97. Now if the foreign impor- tation of goods throws American laborers out of employ- ment, the Cleveland Low Tariff did far less damage than the McKinley High Tariff. Looking further I find that under the Cleveland Tariff we imported $16,000,000 worth of iron and steel, while under the McKinley Tariff, for the same length of time, we imported $53,000,000 worth. Under the Dingley Tariff we imported $12,191,198,006 worth of foreign goods. Under the four years of the Payne-Aldrich Tariff we imported $6,550,446,703 worth of foreign goods. Taking the Protectionist theory that "foreign importations throw American labor out of employment", how can they justify these huge importations under high tariffs. Or do they claim that importations of foreign goods throw labor out of employment only when it comes in under a Democratic Tariff? If their theory is true, then we should not have Tariff Walls but an absolute embargo. But is it true, or is it absolutely false? Now that we have started to reason on the subject, let us follow ir through to the end. Does the importation of Foreign Goods throw our own labor out of employment? The answer to that question is this: it does provided we can import without exporting. If, on the other hand, we must export to the full amount of our imports — dollar for dollar — then the proposition is utterly false. It is not a rational theory but a delusion, a gigantic superstition. No superstition of the Dark Ages could have been more irrational, crude or ignorant. Can We Import Without Exporting? 61 CHAPTER XVIII. Can We Import Without Exporting? Our artist, rising to a sublime vision of International Trade — encompassing the whole earth in his imagination — has endeav- ored to picture to our minds the far-reaching arms of the scales which Equity holds over sea and land; balancing with perfect poise the exchange of equivalences between man and man, be- tween nation and nation, in the vast and complex Commerce of the world. Merely to ask this question — can we import without export- ing — is also to answer it. Every child in the Grammar Grade at school knows that Trade consists, not of one thing but of two things: Imports and Exports. It knows also that each calls for the other, that every dollar's worth of imports requires a dollar's worth of exports; therefore, that to the extent that any people import, they must also export. No matter whether we consume Home Goods or Foreign Goods, we cannot escape the necessity for production. All who consume must produce the equivalent in value of what they consume — or live by charity or theft. And production of wealth is impossible icithout the employment of labor. How can a people import without exporting? How can they export without producing something to export? And how can they produce something to export without employing labor? To these questions there can be but one answer. Therefore, the importation of Foreign Goods does not throw home labor out of employment. On the contrary, importing gives employ- ment to labor. It may change the direction of that employ- ment, but it cannot change the amount of that employment — except to increase it. Take the case of the laborer. Can he import without export- ing? Can he get the necessities of life without giving their equivalent in wealth or service? Take the case of the farmer. Can the farmer import goods, clothing, machinery, hardware, household utensils, etc., without exporting the products of the farm with which to pay for them? If so, how can it be done? And must not his exports equal his imports — unless he goes in debt? And even if he go in debt, he will some time have to 62 TARIFF PRIMER export the equivalent of the debt — which is simply the full equivalent of the imports. Furthermore, how can he have exports — how can he have wheat, corn, oats, potatoes, cotton, etc. — to give in exchange for these imports unless he produces them? And how can he produce them without employing labor — either his own labor or the labor of others? Someone may answer: "He need not produce these home products in order to get the things he desires. If he has the money he can buy them." Quite true. But how can he get the money unless he produces something to be traded for it? And so there is no escape from the necessity of having to produce commodi- ties to be exported equal in value to the imports obtained. Every nation must be self-supporting — or live by theft. Every state, every county, every community must be self-sup- porting, must produce the equivalent of what it consumes. In fact, every individual must be self-supporting, must produce the equivalent of what he himself consumes — unless he live by charity or theft. For example, we must consume enormous quantities of wheat, oats, corn, cotton and potatoes in this country. We must do this — or starve. And in order to get them we must either pro- duce them directly for ourselves, or else produce something else and trade for them. But it is not correct to say, as all Protec- tionists do say, that we can get them either by Production or Trade. We must produce in order to trade. Nor is it correct to say that we can get them either by Industry or by Purchase, that we can either produce or buy. We must produce some- thing to sell in order to get the money with which to buy. No matter how abundantly the other nations of the earth produce the necessities of life, they will not be generous enough to donate them to us — except in case of famine. For every dollar's worth they ship to us they demand a dollar's worth of our products in return. The moment we stop producing for them, they will stop producing for us. How irrational, then, these wild alarms. They are infantile — the product of a crude, narrow and undeveloped brain. They are the result of an utter incapacity to comprehend even the most elementary re- quirements of Trade, BECAUSE TRADE Means Always the Exchange of Equivalences. In the absence of debt, the Law of Trade is this: EVERY Dollar's Worth of Imports Requires a Dollar's Worth of Exports. When debt exists between two indi- Can We Im'port Without Exporting? 63 viduals, or between the people of two nations, then we have a wholly different situation. Then the law is this: the debtor will always export more than he imports — the creditor will always import more than he exports. To show that this is true beyond all reasonable doubt, let us review the cases cited from our history, and show that no matter how great the volume of importations they had to be met with a volume of exports equally great. In fact, they were met with a volume of exports vastly greater — because Up TO 1916 WE Were a Debtor Nation. For instance, while foreign labor was producing for us $2,276,425,051 worth of goods imported under the Cleveland Tariff, American labor was producing for them goods to the amount of $2,741,138,659. Take the case under the McKinley Tariff. While we were "buying" from foreign nations goods to the amount of $2,348,798,006, they were "buying" from us a still larger bill of goods, amounting to $2,770,083,914. Under the Dingley Tariff, as shown before, we imported $12,- 191,198,006 worth of Foreign Goods. Did this diminish the amount of our domestic production, or throw our labor out of employment? It did not. And it did not for the reason that while we imported only that amount of foreign products, the people of foreign lands imported our products to the amount of $18,270,503,750! It is true that we imported $6,550,445,703 worth of goods under the Payne-Aldrich Tariff. But we exported in return goods to the amount of $8,464,511,477. Protectionist speakers all over the country will point to the fact that under what they will call the "free trade" Underwood Tariff, there was dumped into our markets goods to the amount of $22,039,044,693! And these figures will strike terror into the hearts of their hearers! They will probably not couple with this fact the corresponding fact, which is that while foreign labor was filling our orders for goods to this amount, we were filling orders for them aggregat- ing to the colossal sum of $40,999,714,370! Therefore, all the facts and figures in the case show that the importation of foreign goods — no matter how great the amount — instead of throwing labor out of employment, gives employ- ment to labor. And this for the reason that always, and every- where, Imports Must Be Met By Exports, Dollar For Dollar. And what is true of our country is true of every other country on earth. ^ a t' — o uo - ^ ro <^ LH i i $ O (^ to 111 ^ ^ m utT u> i; -s- h hC § o oo • q: oo i q: u a Q. X UJ o5" CO 12 ro 1 1 ! ill j|§B : j^ 11 jK ^^BB^m QJ ca "' 1^^ ^ ^ C£3 \\ >~;l ^^^sSf s^g f ©1 LJO If) o s 7 ^^^^^bB^^ ^ o^ o 1 f ^^ CO oo oo CsJ o ^H m ' oT ©r o' iii! ^E en oo -o C '- cr> «3o ! ', ^ h en V£> «" ."?''= "^ - l!.:! a: q: ro' requi Fori lis cai O S jv^ □ a ^ - c ■= ^ ° .E hi 0. OJ OJ >• g."^ "S ii i z to of ex Inten invest '1 c: ^ ^~ fT3 c: in s^"™ ■i ^ t t on •T3 US S3 S.:t: i2^ S Our "Favorable" Balance of Trade 65 CHAPTER XIX. Our "Favorable" Balance of Trade On the opposite page our artist has pictured Uncle Sam con- fronted with a great problem. In looking over his books our Uncle Sam has discovered that he has been shipping out far more goods than he ever gets any imports for in return. He fears that he has been over-doing it. And so the question in his mind is as to whether it is a gain or a loss to send to foreign countries hundreds of millions of dollars' worth of commodities for which he gets absolutely no commodities in return. That is Exporting Without Importing. Uncle Sam has been told, just as we have been told, that the more goods you send out and the less goods you get back in re- turn, the better you are off. From McKinley to Fordney and McCumber, he has been told that this excess in the exportation of merchandise is one of the many "blessings" which only a Protective Tariff can give. Furthermore, that the excess in the exports of merchandise over imports is made up BY HUGE Importations of Gold! The Protectionist brain has taken special delight in the fact that we ship out hundreds of millions of dollars' worth more than we get back. I presume if we got absolutely no imports in return for our exports, men of the mental type of Fordney, McCumber and their followers, would be happier still. Fur- thermore, they think it the direct result, the necessary effect, of a Protective Tariff. McKinley used to "point with pride" — instead of regret — to the excess of our exports over our im- ports. Then he would exclaim: "IT WILL ALL COME BACK In Shining Gold." But this is not true. WE HAVE ACTUALLY EXPORTED More Gold and Silver Than We Ever Got Back. When he turned to the official reports. Uncle Sam discovered that from 1790 to 1915, he had exported merchandise to the amount of $58,820,315,030. Looking on the other side of the ledger, he finds that he got back in return merchandise amount- ing to $49,999,482,199. That left a balance of $8,820,832,831 which the people of the rest of the world were owing him for the goods he had shipped them. Our "Favorable" Balance of Trade 67 But when our Uncle Sam turned to see if the excess in the importation of bullion was enough to make good this balance, he got the shock of his life. To his amazement he discovered that he had actually exported more gold and silver than he ever got back. Looking at the figures closely he found that there had come back in payment for these goods, which were duly and properly delivered and accepted by the people of foreign lands, only $3,689,895,451. On the other hand, when he turned to see how much gold and silver he had exported, in addition to the huge volume of products he had sent out, he found that his exports of bullion amounted to $5,368,790,625. This was the astound- ing thing. He had actually sent out $1,678,695,174 more of gold and silver than ever came back; leaving a grand total in the excess of exports over imports of $10,499,728,005, for which absolutely nothing came back — but receipted bills. Thus did Uncle Sam discover, as we have now discovered, that this excess of exports over imports does not "come back in shining gold." In fact, that it DOES NOT COME BACK AT All. These vast volumes of exports go, not to get the equi- valent imports in return, but to pay Interest, Dividends and Rent. They are really no part of commerce. They bring nothing in return. They are not an exchange. They stand more in the light of Tribute. Much of them goes across the ocean to pay the royal families of Europe and other large land holders, FOR OUR PRIVILEGE OF LIVING ON AMERICAN Soil. In the cartoon on the opposite page we have a vivid por- trayal of absurd idea that a people are enriched by exporting. With this goes the delusion that a people are injured and im- poverished by importing. Here we see the necessities of life, the raw materials of food and clothing, being loaded on the great ship to be sent to the people of foreign lands. ^ But in the background our artist shows us in a sort of "double exposure" — as they say in motion pictures — showing poverty and want gazing at the spectacle of seeing the things they need going to foreign lands. And yet this in itself is supposed to be beneficial. Whereas, Protectionists would have us believe that if that ship were bringing in and unloading, instead of carrying away, the things of which millions of our people are in need, it should be regarded as an evil, and even disastrous, if too long continued. The cartoon is a portrayal of Exporting without Importing. And that process, whether applied to an indi- 68 TARIFF PRIMER vidual, a family, or a nation — means impoverishment in the end. Congressman Fess, of Ohio, now candidate for United States Senator, in the spring of 1914, claimed that the Underwood Tariff had been a loss to the country of a quarter of a billion of dollars. He made up the loss by adding together the goods we did not export— that was a total loss — -and the goods which we imported. That was also a total loss — to us! Can stupidity and economic nonsense go beyond that? Some one has well said that if a people are impoverished by importing, but are enriched by exporting, then if all the ships that started from all the ports of the world loaded with the ne- cessities of life were to go down in mid-ocean, what a blessing it would be to mankind! Henry George, one of the greatest thinkers the economic world has produced, said: "Commerce is not always the realization of an exchange, but more often THE EXACTION OF A TRIBUTE. When Rome was mistress of the world, Sicily, Spain, Africa, Egypt and Britain exported to Italy far more than they im- ported from Italy. But so far as this excess of their exports over their imports indicating their enrichment, it indicated their impoverishment. It meant that the wealth produced in the provinces was being drained to Rome in taxes and tribute and rent, for which no return was made. "The tribute exacted by Germany from France in 1872 caused a large excess of French exports over imports. So the foreign debt which has been fastened upon Egypt requires large amounts of the produce of that country to be sent away for which there is no return in imports. All war indemnities give rise to a movement in trade which manifests itself on the side of the conquered in exports alone, and on the side of the conquerors in imports— FOLLOWED BY NO RETURN. "If not true already, it will not be many years before the English aristocracy [and royal family] will draw far larger in- comes from their American estates than from their home estates — incomes to supply which we must export without any return in imports." The same process of exporting without importing, is going on all about us. The farmer who must pay interest on debt is constantly exporting more than he imports. The tenant is constantly exporting from the land on which he toils more than he imports. But he does not regard this fact as "favorable" — at least to him. So, likewise, the farmers and fruit growers^ Our "Favorable" Balance of Trade 69 lumbermen and miners, and all other people of the West, are constantly exporting towards the East — where the capitalists who hold their notes and mortgages reside — vastly more than they import from the East. One of the objects of the Fordney-McCumber Tariff, by in- creasing the price of manufactured products more than it can possibly increase the price of farm products, is to still more in- crease this drain of the wealth of the West towards the East — Exporting Without Importing. Owing to our tremendous exportations since 1915 our whole situation has been changed. We are now A CREDITOR NA- TION. From 1915 to 1920, inclusive, our total excess of both merchandise and bullion exported over our imports of merchan- dise and bullion was $18,104,016,451! THIS Is A FINANCIAL AND Industrial Achievement Without A Parallel IN THE History of the World. It changed us from a debtor to a creditor nation. From this point on, if the peoples of Europe pay their debts, OUR IMPORTS WILL EXCEED Our Exports. But our exports still exceed our imports. That means that Europe Is Still Going in Debt to Us. In the present industrial condition of Europe, it may be years to come before she can reverse her position and pay her debts. But when that time does come, no matter when, instead of exporting more than we import — whether we have Protective Tariffs, Revenue Tariffs, or absolute Free Trade — our imports will exceed our exports. Thus have we shown that the seeming exception to the rule that imports and exports are equal, is in no wise due, either to High Tariffs or to Low Tariffs, but to the great fact of Debt — the fact of Dividends, Interest and Rent. Amidst it all every dollar's worth of imports called for a dollar's worth of exports — no more, and no less. The rest went to pay debts, AND Would Have Been Exported if There Had Been No Imports Whatsoever. My Two Islands 71 CHAPTER XX. My Two Islands Now that we are nearing the last chapter, let us get all the threads of thought woven into the warp and woof of one de- cisive and comprehensive Conclusion. And this can be done by answering one specific question: Is TRADE INJURIOUS, OR Is It Beneficial? That is, in brief, the whole issue between Protection and Trade. Both cannot be right. One or the other is wrong. Which is it? If Protection be a good thing, then is Trade a bad thing: because Protection exists only for the prevention of Trade. Ought Trade to be abolished? It ought, if it be a bad thing. Ought Protection to be abolished? It ought, if Trade be a good thing. And so we cannot decide upon the merits of a Protective Tariff until we decide upon the merits of this thing which a Protective Tariff is designed to prevent — namely, Trade, Com- merce, Exchange. That is the issue, and the only issue. I know it has not been put in this form, but that is the verdict which a profound and final analysis must give. What is Trade? Why does it exist? What causes it? Cen- turies and centuries ago, way back in the dim dawn of Civiliza- tion, mankind discovered that by trading and exchanging goods with each other, THEY MULTIPLIED THE PRODUCT- IVENESS OF Their Own Labor. They saw that Trade could be made a mighty agency in the creation of wealth. NO Other Economic Discovery the Human Mind Has Ever Made Can Possibly Compare to the Discovery and Development of Trade. And for the reason that all other discoveries — even Civiliza- tion itself — depend upon the fact of Trade. Without Trade and Commerce no ship would float the sea, no railroad could exist, inventions would be unknown. They all depend upon Trade, Barter, Exchange — Commerce. Abolish Trade and mankind would go back to barbarism and might. The larger part of the human race would perish. The present population of the globe would be utterly impossible without Commerce. Why? Because there cannot be differ- 72 TARIFF PRIMER entiation of employments, there cannot be "division of labor," without Trade. Division of Labor always implies and necessi- tates an exchange either of goods or service. Without Division of Labor, Civilization is impossible. But without Trade there can be no Division of Labor. Each human being must have Food, Clothing and Shelter. He must have these things — or perish. They can be obtained only by labor. They do not exist free. They must be pro- duced. In a just state of society each human being must either produce them directly for himself, or produce something else and trade for them. To illustrate the Law of Trade our artist has pictured for us two islands located quite near each other. One we will call "Coal Island". The average returns of labor expended in digging coal are a ton a day — six tons a week. The other we will call "Wheat Island", because its soil is favorable to the production of wheat. On the average, it yields a bushel of wheat a day to labor — six bushels a week. But it is unfavor- able for the production of coal. While it has mines, yet the veins are so thin that it takes a week's labor to produce a single ton of coal. But on Coal Island, were they to engage in the growing of wheat, their wages would be just the reverse of those on Wheat Island. Since it would take a week's labor, on the average, to grow a bushel of wheat, the wages for labor would be only one bushel of wheat a week. Nor is this difference due in any degree to the productiveness of the laborers themselves. IT Is DUE TO THE DIFFERENCE IN THE Productiveness of Land in Reference to These Two Products. The same amount of labor which will produce one bushel of wheat on Coal Island, will produce six bushels on Wheat Island. And the same in reference to coal. Let us now introduce Trade, Commerce, between the two islands and see the manifold blessings that will come to the people of each island. The people on the Wheat Island must have coal as well as wheat. If, instead of producing coal for themselves, they produced wheat and traded it to their neigh- bors for coal, The Productiveness of their Labor Would Be Increased Six Fold. In other words, by the mere fact of Trade the normal, natural wages of their labor will be increased 500% — measured in terms of coal. They now have six tons of coal as the result of their labor, instead of one. My Two Islands 73 How stands the case with the people on Coal Island? They must have wheat as well as coal in order to live. If, instead of producing wheat directly for themselves, they produce coal and trade it for wheat, they will have six bushels of wheat in- stead of one as the result of their labor. And so Trade has also increased their wages 500% — measured in terms of wheat. And these are the results, in principle, which follow from Trade everywhere, in all countries, under all forms of government. Thus do we see that Trade is in itself A PRODUCER OF Wealth. This fact mankind discovered centuries ago. Furthermore, we see how Trade makes each country a composite of all lands and climes; so that — barring the cost of transporta- tion — the result is the same as if each island produced equally well both wheat and coal. We see also that Trade does not enable the people to live from the labor of others, but that EACH PRODUCES THE EQUIVALENT OF ALL THAT IT CONSUMES. It is the labor of the men in the wheat fields of Wheat Island that produce the coal which they consume. How do they do this? By devoting themselves exclusively to the production of wheat — thus pro- ducing an excess beyond their own needs — they make it possible for the people on Coal Island to devote themselves exclusively to the production of coal. And the people on Coal Island as certainly produced the wheat on Wheat Island which they con- sume, as tho they went over there and sowed the seed and reaped the harvest for themselves. Now suppose the owners of the coal land on Wheat Island should come before their Congress and say: "Why should we 'buy' our coal? Why not produce it for ourselves? Let us start a new industry, keep this money at home, and give em- ployment to our own labor by producing our coal instead of buying it. Why give employment to the laborers on Coal Island by having them produce all our coal for us? Why put ourselves at the mercy of these 'foreigners'? Give us a Tariff high enough, say 600%, and we will start a new industry on this island." (Gentle reader, is not this a familiar argument?) And so they build a High Tariff Wall around Wheat Island for the "protection" of Producers of coal. At the end of the year, it is true, the owners of the coal lands on Wheat Island can "point with pride" to a new industry. No question about that. There it stands. The island now produces its coal in- stead of buying it. But what is the result? What effect upon the total wealth of the island? 74 TARIFF PRIMER This appalling result: Measured in terms of coal, they have only one-sixth as much wealth as they would have had by produc- ing wheat and trading for coal. In other words, the natural wages of labor is only one-sixth under a protective Tariff of what it was under the former Free Trade. Has labor been given more employment than before? Not at all. It has simply been diverted, diverted from the most productive channels of employ- ment into the least productive channels. And by so doing it has not increased the amount of its employment. But it has diminished its wages to one-sixth of what they were before! Apply the same principle to Coal Island and the same result follows. The labor which was formerly engaged in the pro- duction of coal is now employed in the production of wheat. True it is they are now producing their wheat instead of buying it— but at a TREMENDOUS Economic Loss. The rewards of labor are only a sixth of what they were under the former Free Trade. Furthermore, at the end of the year the total wealth of the island is only one-sixth of what it would have been had the people produced coal — the thing they can produce to the best advantage — and traded coal for the other necessity of life which the people on Wheat Island can produce to the best ad- vantage. This simple illustration enables us to see the full working of the principle of Trade. And to this law there is no exception. There can be none. It is as universal as the law of gravitation. Substitute continents for islands. Substitute hundreds of products for only two products, and the result is still the same. Here again, we see the great economic truth, the truth that there are two ways by which the people of any country can obtain the necessities of life. One way is to produce them di- rectly for themselves. The other way is to produce something else and trade for them. If left free, the people will take which- ever course gives them THE GREATEST RESULTS FOR THE Least Amount of Labor. The principles governing Trade between the people of differ- ent nations are identical with the principles governing trade be- tween the people of the same community. The motive is the same in both, the cause is the same in both. And the results are the same in both. ALL ECONOMISTS ARE AGREED ON That Point. If buying the necessities of life instead of producing them direct, throws labor out of employment in the nation, it will throw labor out of employment in each family. If the money My Two Islands 75 which goes out beyond our borders for goods — a thing which in reality never happened, because trade is the exchange of goods for goods and not of goods for money — then the money paid out by each family for the necessities of life would be a positive loss. There was a time back in the Pioneer Days when each house- hold produced practically everything that it consumed. It was a complete economic unit in itself. Each family not only grew its own wool, but carded it, spun it into yarn, wove the yarn into cloth, and then made the cloth into clothing. With the coming of the Factory System all was changed — revolutionized. Barring garden products and a few other food products, the vast majority of all the families in America today produce absolutely nothing in the finished form which they themselves consume! And yet no rational mind would claim for a moment that this has diminished the productiveness of wealth, or the wages of labor. On the contrary, it has greatly increased both — multiplying them many fold. And yet all this industrial progress was made possible only by the fact of Trade — both domestic and foreign. This broad view of International Trade enables us the better to see how perfectly the Fordney-McCumber idea of things represents what Darwin called "arrested development" — or, better still, "reversion to previous type." The idea which builds High Tariff Walls in the world of today, belongs to that primitive, undeveloped brain so splendidly adjusted to the prim- itive economic conditions when Trade was unknown, when every "foreigner" was a foe, and when each family, or clan, produced All the Things That It Consumed. The illustration of the Two Islands enables us to see, also, that the so-called "cost of production" theory is part and parcel of the Protectionist theory. If the one falls, and fall it must, the other goes down with it. Now just what is the limitation which the cost-of-production theory places on the avarice and rapacity of the "protected" Interests? This theory is that the tariff rate on Foreign Goods shall be no higher than is necessary to raise their cost to home Consumers to that price level actually required in order to make a "reasonable profit" on the competing Home Goods. For example, the cost-of-production theory would say to the owners of wheat lands on Coal Island: "You can have a tariff of 500% on your wheat, but you cannot have a tariff rate of a 1000% or of even 600%. Such rates would be excessive, 'un- conscionable' — extortionate." But I submit to you that to 76 TARIFF PRIMER pass such a law as will enable the Producers of wheat on Coal Island to compel the Consumers of wheat to pay even six times as much for wheat as they would have to pay in the Open Mar- ket — or any price above the Open Market Price — is also ex- tortion. Furthermore, if the "difference in the cost of production at home and abroad" could be accurately determined and equalized thru Tariff Rates — a physical and mathematical impossibility — what would be its effects on the world? Simply this: It would deprive the whole human race of the enormous and in- calculable benefits and blessings of Commerce — AND MAKE THE SUPPORT FO THE PRESENT POPULATIOM OF THE GLOBE IMPOSSIBLE! In 1846, as the result of 20 years of intense struggle and agitation, led by Richard Cobden and John Bright, England abolished her Corn Laws — tariffs on farm products. It did not establish Free Trade, because the products of Trade were still taxed. But it did abolish the principle of Protection. No tariffs were levied on foreign products competing with similar home products. It is to me the most dramatic, heroic and in- tellectual period in English History. As the result of the long campaign in the principles of Poli- tical Economy and Free Trade which Cobden and his followers had conducted, Lord John Russell, in a letter to his London constituents in 1845, wrote as follows: "I used to be of the opinion that corn was an exception to the general rule of poli- tical economy." He had supposed that while there should be Free Trade in everything else, there should be Protection in foodstuffs. He had now changed his mind, for he ended his letter by saying: "Let us, then, put an end to a system which has proved to be the blight of commerce, the bane of agricul- ture, the source of bitter division among classes, the cause of penury, fever, mortality and crime among the people." The reader is referred to Ridpath's "Universal History" for a most dramatic account of this mighty event in human history. He is also referred to a Chapter in "The Tariff and the Trusts" by Franklin Pierce: "How England Got Free Trade." I will suggest also a small book recently published in England under the title: "The Hungry Forties." This book is made up entirely of letters and interviews of the "oldest inhabitants" whose memories went back to the direful days in England when she had a Protective Tariff. It was edited by a daughter of Richard Cobden, Mrs. Cobden Unwin. It is the best detailed My Two Islands 77 history of the economic condition of the common people of England that has ever been written. Ridpath thus presents the terrible conditions which existed under a Protective Tariff in England :"Circumstances favored, as they have rarely favored, the cause of the reforming party. That most unanswerable of all arguments, Human Misery, came to the aid of the propaganda. Wretchedness, woe, want, starvation, despair, uttered their voices, and the cry at length reached the profoundest recesses of prejudice and conservatism. It reverberated through the Kingdom. The towns were shaken at first and then the countryside began to heave and swell. It was not, as we have said, the voice of man, but the voice of hunger, of thirst, The CLAMOR OF WOMEN AND Children for Bread." In his great debate on the Tariff with James G. Blaine, in the North American Review — back in the 80's — Gladstone showed that the abolition of Protection in England had increased the wages of the working classes of England 100%. It thus in- creased their wages by INCREASING Their PURCHASING Power. Every Protectionist in Congress has had to admit that wages are higher in England than in any other country in Europe, and that they are lotvest where there is the highest "Protection." In short, there can be no hope for the abolition of Poverty, or the abolition of War, until this country — and all other coun- tries — substitute for the iniquitous Class Legislation of Pro- tective Tariffs, the maxim of Thomas Jefferson: EQUAL Rights for All— Special Privileges to None. Therefore, whatever obstructs the free working of this univer- sal, world-wide Law of Trade, Is TO THE Detriment of the Human Race. Whoever favors its obstruction, whoever ad- vocates the enactment of a Protective Tariff, is doing all in his power To INCREASE THE AMOUNT OF LABOR WHICH MAN- KIND Must Perform In Order to Live. He is not friend but foe. While his ignorance of the fact that this effect will follow, and always has followed, may exempt him from moral condemnation; IT DOES NOT EXEMPT THE HUMAN RACE From the Disastrous Effects of Building Tariff Walls. Revenue Tariffs vs. Protective Tariffs 79 CHAPTER XXL Revenue Tariffs vs. Protective Tariffs There are two distinct classes of Tariff Walls. And this for the reason that there are two distinct theories, or Systems of Thought, relative to the Tariff— the PROTECTIVE THEORY and the REVENUE THEORY. The Protective Theory has been associated with the Repub- lican Party almost from the beginning of its history, but found its first distinctive expression in the High Tariffs of 1867 and 1870. The doctrine of "Tariff for Revenue only" has been pro- claimed and defended by the Democratic Party thruout its long history, dating back to its founder, Thomas Jefferson. Turning to the illustration, the first thing that strikes our attention is the fact that the PROTECTIVE TARIFF WALL is much higher than the REVENUE TARIFF WALL — more than twice as high. This fundamental distinction has set the two parties directly against each other in the framing of every Tariff Bill from 1867 down to the Fordney-McCumber Tariff. Why is it that one party always wants high tariff rates, the other always wants low tariff rates? This direct conflict be- tween them is due wholly to the attitude of each political party in reference to taxing the general public — not for the support of the Government— But For THE SUPPORT AND ENRICH- MENT OF Private Individuals and Corporations. On this vital issue the Republican Party affirms and the Democratic Party denies; declaring that the RIGHT TO TAX begins and ends IN THE Needs OF THE GOVERNMENT; and that no party, and no government, has the right to tax the general public FOR THE Benefit of Private Individuals — unless they are recognized as paupers, or are justly entitled to government bounty for military service in defence of the state. As pointed out in Chapter X, the increased price of Foreign Goods, due to the Tariff, goes into the Public Treasury. This I have called the Revenue Branch of the Tariff. The increased price of Home Goods, due to the Tariff on Foreign Goods, goes into Private Pockets. This is the Protective Branch of the Tariff. To it the Democratic Party is utterly opposed. 80 TARIFF PRIMER On the other hand, the Repubhcan Party for generations has staked its claims to the suffrage of the American people on the fact that at every opportunity it has made the stream of wealth which the Tariff pours into private pockets just As LARGE As It Could Be Made, regarding the production of that stream of wealth as the real object of a Tariff. With the Revenue Theory, raising revenue for the govern- ment is the only legitimate purpose of a Tariff. It regards the increased price of Home Goods resulting as purely "incidental", undesirable, but practically inevitable under this mode of taxa- tion. But it makes this contribution to the enrichment of private individuals as small as possible by levying low rates in- stead of high rates. With the Protective Theory, on the other hand, raising revenue for the Government is purely "incidental"; while rais- ing revenue for private pockets is the real purpose in taxing Foreign Goods. It maintains that the whole prosperity and industrial progress of the nation is due to the employment of this "policy" in the past. It stands for High Tariffs. Not that the party is opposed to raising government revenue by Indirect Taxation — of which the Tariff is the most iniqui- tous form. It favors this mode of taxation. It was the Demo- cratic Party that took the first step towards taxing the people, not on their necessities, but in proportion to their ABILITY TO Pay. There was embodied in the Underwood Tariff a Gradu- ated Income Tax. Later on, the Wilson Administration sup- plemented this with a Corporation Tax, an Inheritance Tax, and an Excess Profits Tax. THIS WAS THE GREATEST Step Towards Social Justice that Has Been Made IN Taxation Since the Founding of the Republic! Great is the contrast between raising Government revenues by a Tariff tax, and raising them by a Graduated Income and Corporation Tax. One is a tax on Want, the other is a tax on Wealth. One is a tax on Necessities, the other is a tax on Possessions. One is a tax on what you must get in order to live, the other is a tax on what you actually have. In short, one is a tax on Expenditures — the other is a tax on Incomes. The reason for the change was clearly stated by Senator Underwood— then Chairman of the Ways and Means Com- mittee — when he introduced his bill in the House, April 23, 1913. He said: "The Democratic Party stands for a Tariff for revenus only, with em- phasis on the 'only'. We do not propose to tax one man for the benefit of an- Revenue Tariffs vs. Protective Tariffs 81 other, except for the necessary revenue we must raise to administer this government economically." "The time has come in this country when the great untaxed wealth of America must and shall bear its fair share of the burden of running the government of the United States. We remove the taxes at the custom house on necessaries purposely to levy a tax on wealth." The fact must not be overlooked that the Underwood Tariff, to the extent of its rates, was a Protective Tariff. Any Tariff, no matter how low, yields "protection." Senator Underwood himself has steadily maintained that the rates in his Tariff are excessive in reference to cotton and woolen goods. Custom house reports show them going as high as 60% in 1921. Mill- ions were made under them by the American manufacturers of these goods. And yet the Fordney Tariff has more than doubled these rates on cotton and woolen goods. I maintain that the Underwood Tariff was the best tariff measure ever enacted in this country. It was so for three reasons: First, because it contained a Graduated Income Tax, later on supplemented by a Corporation Tax, Inheritance Tax, etc. Second, because it put practically all raw materials on the Free List. Third, because the rates on its "dutiable" goods are lower than in any previous Tariff since the Civil War. There are three ways by which the Underwood Tariff can be improved: (1) Extend and perfect its forms of Direct Taxation. (2) Gradually put on the Free List all products that are con- tinuously sold in foreign countries. (3) Lower its excessive rates on cotton and woolen goods. The tendency of the present Administration has been, and will continue to be, not to raise but to lower the direct taxes on the millionaires and "swollen fortunes" of the country, thus throwing the burden more and more on the toiling millions thru Indirect Taxation — the Tariff, Sales Taxes, Luxury Taxes, etc. The issue in this country is the issue in every country. Tariff Taxes and other forms of Indirect Taxation have been the means thruout the whole of recorded history for the plunder, impoverishment and oppression of mankind. Thus does there emerge from the Tariff Issue the one great issue of all the ages. That issue is this: (1) to abolish all forms of Indirect Taxation. (2) To stop taxing people for the support and enrichment of Privileged Classes, taxing them only for the support of the Government. (3) And to tax them for it, not on their necessities, But in Proportion to Their Ability to Pay. Then, and not till then, will we have an honest System of Taxation — A Real Repubuc! 82 TARIFF PRIMER APPENDIX TOTAL IMPORTS AND EXPORTS OF MERCHANDISE AND BULLION FROM 1790 TO 1921 (Fiscal Years Ending June 30th) YEARS IMPORTS 1790 23,000.000 1791 29,200.000 1792 31.500.000 1793 31.100,000 1794 34.600,000 1795 69.756,268 1796 81,436,164 1797 75,379,406 1798 68,551,700 1799 79,069,148 Total 523,592,686 1800 91,252,768 1801 111,363,911 1802 76,333,333 1803 64,666,666 1804 85,000,000 1805 120,600,000 1806 129,110,000 1807 138,500,000 1808 56,990,000 1809 59,400,000 Total 933,216,678 1810 85,400,000 1811 53,400,000 1812 77,030,000 1813 22,005,000 1814 12,965,000 1815 113,041,274 1816 147,103,000 1817 99.250.000 1818 121,750,000 1819 87,125,000 Total 819,069,274 1820 74,454,000 1821 62,585,724 1822 83,241,541 1823 77,579,267 1824 80.548,142 1825 96,340,075 1826 84,974,477 1827 79,484,068 1828 88,509,824 1829 74,492.527 Total 802,209.645 EXPORTS 20,205,156 19,012,041 20,753,098 26,109,572 33,043,725 47,989,872 58,574,625 51,294,710 61,327,411 78,665,522 416,975,732 70,971,780 93,020,513 71,957,144 55,008.033 77,699,074 95,566.021 101,536,963 108,343,150 22,430,960 52,203,233 748,736,871 66,757,970 61,316,832 38,527,236 27,856,017 6,927,441 52,557,753 81,920.062 87,671,569 93,281,133 70,142,521 586,958,534 69,691,669 65.074.382 72,160.281 74,699,030 75,986,657 99,535,388 77,595,322 82,324,827 72,264,686 72,358,671 761,690,913 Excess of Imports 2,794,844 10,187,959 10,746,902 4,990,428 1,556,275 21,766,396 22,861,539 24,084,696 7,224,289 403,626 106,616,954 20.280,988 18,343,398 4,376,189 9,658,633 7,300,926 25,033,979 27,573,037 30,156,850 34,559,040 7,196,767 184,479,807 18,642,030 38,502,764 6,037,559 60,483,521 65,182,938 11,578,431 28,468,867 16,982,479 245.878,589 4,762.331 11,081,260 2,880,237 4,561,485 7,379,155 16,245,138 2.133,856 49,043,462 Excess of Exports 7,916,832 5,851,107 13.767.849 2,488.658 3.195.313 2,840.759 8.524.730 Imports and Exports from 1790 to 1921 83 YEARS IMPORTS EXPORTS Excess of Imports Excess of Exports 1830 70.876,920 73.849,508 2.972,588 1831 103,191,124 81.310.583 21,880,541 1832 101.029.266 87.176,943 13,852,323 00 1833 108,118,311 90,140,433 17,977.878 00 1834 126,521,332 104,336,973 22,184 359 1835 149,895,742 121,693,577 28,202,165 «- 1836 189,980,035 128,663,040 61,316,995 c .2 1837 140,989.217 117,419,376 23,560,841 1 1838 113,717,404 108,426,616 5,290,788 1 ' 1839 Total 162,092,132 121,028,416 41,063,716 235,338.606 o 1,266,411,483 1,034,045,465 2.972,588 "o 1840 107.141,519 132,085,946 24,944,427 £ 1841 127.946.177 121,851.803 6,094,374 SS (-1 1842 100,162,087 104,691.534 4,529.447 1843 64,753 799 84,346,480 19.592.681 1844 108,435,035 111,200,046 2,765.011 1845 117,254.564 114,646,606 2,607,958 ^ 1846 121.691.797 113,488,516 8.203,281 r 1847 146.545,638 158,648,622 12,102,98* 1848 154,998,928 154,032,131 966,797 « ■«)< 1849 Total 147,857,439 145.755,820 1,240,747,504 2.101,619 00 1,196,786,983 19.974.029 63.934.550 1850 178,138,218 151,898,720 26.239.498 ^ H 1851 216,224,932 218,388,011 2,163,079 3 1852 212,054.442 209,658,366 3.296,076 1853 267,978,647 230,976,157 37,002,490 > V 1854 304.562,381 278,325,268 26,237,113 1855 261,468,520 275,156,846 13,688,326 4J 1856 314,639,942 326,964,908 12,324.966 i 1857 360,890,141 362,960,682 2.070.541 1858 282,613,150 324.644,421 42.031.271 1859 . Total 338,768,130 356,789,462 18.021.332 2,738,238.503 2,735,762.841 92.775.177 90.299.515 / 1860 362.166,254 400,122,296 37.956.042 w 1861 335,650,153 249.344.913 86.305,340 'S 1862 205,771,729 227.558.141 21,786.412 H 1863 252,919,920 268,121,058 15,201,138 ;« ^ 1864 329,562,895 264 234,529 65,328,366 1865 248,555,652 233,672.529 14,883,123 1866 445,512,158 434,903.593 10,608,565 1867 417,831,571 355.374,513 62,457.058 1868 371,624,808 375,733,001 4,108.193 1869 Total 437,314,255 343,256,077 94,058,178 3.406,909,395 3,152.320.650 333,640,530 79,051,785 84 TARIFF PRIMER YEARS IMPORTS EXPORTS Excess of Imports Excess of Exports 1870 462.377.587 450.927,434 11,450.153 1871 541,493.708 541.262.166 231.542 1872 640.338.766 524,055,120 116,283.646 1873 663,617.147 607,088,496 56,528.651 1874 595,861.248 652.913,445 57.052.197 1875 553,906.153 605,574,853 51.668,700 1876 476,677,871 596,890.973 120,213,102 1877 492,097,540 658.637.455 166,539,917 1878 466,872,846 728.605.891 261,733,045 1879 Total 466.073,775 735,436,882 269.363,107 5.359.316,641 6,101,392,717 184,493,992 926,570,068 1880 760.989.056 852,781,577 91.792,521 1881 753.240,125 921,784.193 168,544,068 1882 767,111,964 799,959,736 32,847,772 1883 751.670.305 855.659.735 103,989,430 > 18S4 705,123,955 807,646.992 102.523 037 1885 620,769,652 784,421.280 163.651.628 1886 674,029,792 751.988,240 77,958.448 1887 752,490,560 752,180.902 309,658 1888 783,295.100 742,368,690 40,926,410 1889 Total 774.094,725 839,042,908 64.948,183 7.342.815.234 8,107.834,253 41,236,068 806,255,087 ^ 1890 823,286,735 909,977,104 86,690,369 ' 1891 881,175,643 993,434,452 112.258,809 1892 897,057,002 1,113,284,034 216,227,032 1893 910,768,555 997,083,357 86,314,802 , 1894 740,730,293 1,019.569,898 278.839,605 1895 788.565,904 921.301.932 132,736,028 1896 842,026,925 1,055,558,555 213,531,630 1897 880,278,419 1,153,301.774 273,023,355 ' 1898 767,369,109 1.301.993.960 534.624,851 1899 Total 816,778,148 1.320.864.443 504,086,295 8,348,036.733 10.786,369,509 2,438.332.776 1900 929.770.670 1.499,462,116 569.691.446 1901 925.609,873 1,605,235,348 679.625.475 1902 983.574.456 1,480,020.741 496.446.285 1903 1,094.864,755 1,511.482,533 416,617.778 1904 1,117,911,553 1,591,759,959 473.848,406 1905 1,198,646,897 1,660,004,502 461.357.605 1906 1,367,226,716 1,848,307.154 481,080,438 1907 1.591.878.298 1.988.989,327 397,111,029 1908 1.387.337,210 1,991,127.472 603.790.262 1909 ^ Total 1,399,879.023 1,810,225.714 410.346,691 11.996.699,451 16.986,614,866 4,989,915.415 Imports and Exports from 1790 to 1921 85 t YEARS IMPORTS EXPORTS Excess of Imports Excess of Exports ' 1910 1.645,504,529 1.918.834.796 273.230,267 1911 1,646,770,367 2.136.579.810 489.809,443 1912 1.749,251,653 2.326,541.422 577,289,769 1913 1.923,470,775 2,615.261.082 691,790,307 1914 1.990,790,920 2.531,582.700 540.791.780 1915 1.878.848,818 2.965,755.675 1,086,906,857 1916 2,731,047,186 4.483.523.956 1.752.476.770 1917 3,671,534,774 6.660.249.580 2.988.714.806 1918 3,140.407.039 6.249.744.994 3.109.337.955 1918 1.533.363,204 3.353.497.069 1.820.133.865 1919 4,070.308,996 8,527,632,289 4.457,323.293 1920 5,783.609.804 8,663.723.739 2.880,113.935 Total 31,764,908,065 52.432.927.112 20,668.019,047 1921 2,509,147,570 4.485.031.356 1,975,883,786 Total 34.274.055.635 56.917,958.468 23.643.902,833 Congressman Fess, of Ohio — in 1914 — is reported to have said: "Any in- dustrial history of the United States shows that our export trade began with the Crimean war, back in the fifties." No greater distortion of the facts of history is possible. It was to refute the volumes of such Protectionist false- hoods that, with much patient research, I have given the reader the above table. It is a liberal education in itself as to our Foreign Trade, carried thru 131 years of history. The successive Tariffs are also given. Study the two together. Make your own deductions as to what extent, and how, Tariff Walls affect our Foreign Trade. 1 b.^ir o> 'O H «s cj o ^ e^ >o ^^ **> 1 ^ -*- 0- ■T i q v9 to ^o 2 OCL- V? »^ va t^ >o :5 o-' lil i/i ■4i <»-" ■^ o o ^ fc h "O o bS o Uo ^» tv. O ir o a X LU to •a- * •^ to -3^ vS cS J2 bo &- !>: ■3- I . D-r ^ tao lO '^iL'^ K) 'N CS Q J ^^ LO .13 ■I- o Lu:^c 1 r^" >>o o J- 3 — •3- -J- 0-" o ^ v* ^ vfi- or |||D-" z o ^ o ^ a ■a^ C3 W o 1- o o CO O" J~ o <^ vO T>" — ^ •^ o ■*" o «n — 3 >o a= r^ OtT o or "> t^ -»- 5 S ♦O r~ ■a- o (to v5) ■>- o Oo ID o o" vft !f2 -3- 2J u o 2 o < 5 e 2: o O a •< -J to UJ "a i £ 111 o O 1 CO F o UJ ■< -J Q. P A Study in World Commerce 89 A STUDY IN WORLD COMMERCE The two preceding charts are designed to give the reader a general vision of the World's production of twelve leading commodities. These charts will give you stronger and clearer convictions of the abso- lute necessity for International Trade than you ever had before. No one can have a true idea of Trade who does not include in his mental picture the whole of the 1,702,000,000 of the earth's inhabitants, realizing that each one of them must have food, clothing and shelter — and must have them daily. When taking this broad view of Trade we recognize the fact that the Exchange of wealth is as necessary as the Production of wealth. Without Trade, no advance is possible beyond that crude, primitive condition in which each human being — like the lower orders of animals — must provide for himself all of life's necessities. Civilized life requires that hundreds of products shall enter into the daily use and consumption of each human being. No human being produces scarcely even one of them for himself in its entirety. How, then, can he get all the rest of them. Only by producing something in excess of his own needs — and trading his surplus for the rest. What is true of the individual is true of nations. Countries in which the Production of any given product exceeds its Consumption, must export their excess to the scores of countries in which its Consumption exceeds its Production. That alone is the law, and THE UNIVERSAL PROCESS of CiviUzed life. The first two tables give a comparative view of the sources of supply for 12 leading commodities, together with the six countries producing them most abundantly. In reference to any one of the products listed, it is probable that all of the six countries imder it Produce more of it than they Consume. Hence the necessity for Exporting. But if you go on down the line of the countries producing it, you will soon reach those that produce less of it than they Consume. Add to these the scores of other countries not producing it at all; and yet, which must consume it in order to live. Now how can they get these commodities of which they Consume more than they Produce, except by Importing? But how could they import if there were no such thing as International Trade? THUS DO WE SEE THAT COMMERCE IS AS ESSENTIAL TO THE LIFE OF OUR EARTH'S INHABITANTS AS THE AIR THEY BREATHE. This brings us to the table on the opposite page. It shows us that Com- merce is in itself a perfect system of International Bookkeeping. "The equity of it is so exact that it balances all accounts with perfect precision. Excess of Production over Consumption, as in the case of Corn, is balanced by an Excess of Exports over Imports. On the other hand, the excess of Consumption over Production — as shown in the case of Flax Seed, Wool and Sugar — must be made up by an Excess of Imports over Exports. And since we must import them — or go without —WHY SHOULD WE INCREASE THEIR COST TO OURSELVES BY A TARIFF WALL? So broad and fundamental is the truth here expressed, that the table can be applied to each household — and to each individual. Here is an outline 80 universal in its scope, that it can be applied to every product in reference to each nation, and in reference to each of the hundreds of millions of humanity! c O T' ^ ^^^^^^^^^^1 cr- o □ _i cr o cr- O o > A o • •z. o « M oO o OO oO OO o <^ OO o OO o oo o CO CO o o _l _J Uj no UJ q: o "^■i 1 Har and Prices, 1 1 For iii Years. | tr 1 q: o z: U —1 o < -z. "^^■^1 > o o o J lo o vn OO 1 Effects of War on Prices 91 EFFECTS OF WAR ON PRICES On the opposite page is a graphic portrayal of the rise and fall of prices, due to War. It pictures to the eye and the imagination the Story of World Prices for a period of 112 years. This remarkable diagram was given in the "Literary Digest" several months ago. The Napoleonic Wars really began with Napoleon's Italian Campaign in 1796, terminating with the battle of Waterloo, June 18, 1815. The aver- age prices in all the markets of the world reached their highest peak by the end of the following year. Then, as shown in the diagram, the Interna- tional Market Price dropped fully 100% in the next two or three years. Prices continued to decHne thruout the earth between 1820 and 1830, rose slightly before 1840, and again made a rapid decline between 1840 and 1850. They rose again between 1850 and 1860. Then came the lamentable war between the North and the South, which ended April 9, 1865. Prices reached their highest point in the world's market about 1867. In this country the general Price Level was continued to about 1870, or '72. They dropped nearly 150% in the Worid's Market by 1880. The international Price Level continued steadily to decline down to 1897. In this country scores of products did not reach their lowest point until 1900, but the lowest average for all products was reached about 1897. Then, both for this country and the world, prices steadily rose up to the opening of the World War. From that date to 1920, the International Price Level rose fully 150%, according to the diagram, reaching a higher peak than during the Civil War, and to as high a level as was attained at the close of the Napoleonic Wars. This gives us a World Vision, projected thru 112 years of history, of the law of Supply and Demand. Thus, over and beyond the reach of the narrow provincial minds, which cannot see beyond the borders of their own little state or province — and which think that by building Tariff Walls they can keep the prices of their own products out of the mighty stream of price currents which sweeps round the whole earth — rises the supreme law of the economic world, the law of Supply and Demand. Each human being is a part of this universal Demand, and furnishes some portion of its universal SuppHes, if a Wealth Producer. It is not local, but general. It is in operation everywhere. While there are as many markets — as many Demands for the necessities of life — as there are human beings, yet this great Economic Law sees all mankind, not as many, but as One. AH the millions of nature's children are but units in that great Social Organism which spreads itself across national boundaries, reaching from pole to pole, round the whole earth — binding all mankind into one supreme Demand for the necessities of life. Then it calls upon every land and clime, every race and nation, to furnish the material products which can feed the hungers and satisfy the needs of this grand total of wants of all humanity. And the Social Organism distributes its supplies among the teeming miUions of its units just as perfectly as does the Physical Organism^ach in accordance to its Needs. The Price of any product is always highest where its Needs are greatest. It is the relation of the quantity of the Supply to the quantity of the Demand of each human being, that makes up that vast and complex thing, called the World's Market Price. "Who knows what earth needs from earth's lowliest creatures?" Only the law of Supply and Demand can tell us. Price History from 1850 to 1920 93 PRICE HISTORY FROM 1850 TO 1920 In the diagram on the opposite page is presented to the eye of the reader the History of Prices in our own country, from 1850 to 1920, taken from the U. S. Statistical Abstract. I have given the average price for the five years, ending with the close of the five year period. The price of Bar Iron is the number of dollars a ton, the price of Wool is by the pound, and the price of Cotton Sheeting is by the yard. The important thing in the diagram is its showing of the general trend of prices. What is true of these three products is true of the Price Level of all domestic products for the 70 years charted, and also of the World Price Level, as shown in the previous chart. Tariffs or no Tariffs, they run paral- lel with the World Price Level— THEY ALL GO UP OR DOWN TO- GETHER. If you have been reading, or hearing. Protectionists' speeches of late, you would say that the period from 1850 to 1860 must have been under High Protective Tariffs, And that the period from 1865 to 1900 must have been under those Democratic "free trade" Tariffs. But the facts are almost wholly the other way. By looking at the top of the diagram you will see that the period from 1850 to 1860, was under the Walker Revenue Tariff of 1846, with average rates of only 25%. In 1857 these rates were reduced to about 18%. We entered the war on that basis. In fact, the only nominally "free trade" period in our whole history was from 1861 to about 1867. During this period, when tariffs were laid on Foreign Goods, they were also laid on similar Home Goods — and they were laid on Home Goods first! That is, external revenues were balanced with internal revenues. Abraham Lincoln was elected President in 1860. From that date to 1913, is a period of 53 years. Of those 53 years, only three of them were under a Democratic Tariff. I refer to the Cleveland Tariff, from 1894 to 1897 — and which was so much of a "protectionist" measure that he refused to sign it! The whole of the remaining 50 years — quite a long stretch — were lived under RepubUcan Tariffs. AND YET PRICES WENT DOWN* Beginning with 1867, they were all High Protective Tariffs. The Tariff of 1883 increased the rates in the Tariffs of 1867 and 1870. The McKinley Tariff of 1890 made them still higher. The rates in the Dingley Tariff of 1897 were outrageous, tho slightly lower than those of the McKinley Tariff; while the Payne-Aldrich Tariff of 1909 increased the rates in the Dingley outrage. There you have our Tariff History and our Price History side by side. Take the case of wool. In 1867 it was given the highest rate in our history. And yet the price of wool went down. It declined rapidly till 1870. It averaged about eight cents a pound higher for the next five years. Was there an increase in the Tariff Rate? On the contrary, there was a 10% reduction of this rate, and of all rates, in 1872. The Tariff of 1883 restored the rates of 1867. And yet the price of wool continued steadily to go down — on thru the period covered by the McKinley High Tariff. The Cleveland Tariff put wool on the Free List. But the decline in its price was nothing as compared to its decline under the previous 27 years of High Protection. This chart ought to remove from the brain of the reader the last trace of the whole "obsession" of Protection. • No theory of Prices can be sound which does not also consider the volume of the world • Money in its relation to the volume of the world's exchanges, and of the wealth in exchang* — 1 ^ ^ 5^ •• ~3 o ■"" m -^ ^ ^ / / ^ 1- / ^ / y z' ^ lU / t' n 2 >- 1 / r LU p:- i / tr /^ y V LJ /^ to \ o / / J_ / / 1 1 1 o >- ^' .^ / /^ i— J / / / z / 1 ^1 ^ / \ \ S s s y y y^ / > s N "V X V, ?- OO ir> ?- ■>»■ ? C3 ^■-:, -^ ^^ -5^ s S Li_l 2 \ N, \ > / / 1— < «-» ~ __,, .^ -' UJ -J ^ /^ ^ Li_ 2 \ S Ll_ 2: ^> \ ^ *^ y Ctrl < ■ \ s ^ X ^ •g Tariff Rates from Custom House Reports 95 A STUDY IN TARIFF RATES FROM CUSTOM HOUSE REPORTS The average rates collected at the Custom House do not correspond WITH THE AVERAGE RATES IN ANY TARIFF BILL. THEY ARE ALWAYS LOWER. This is due to the fact that the highes trates in all Protective Tariffs tend to be prohibitive. They must be prohibitive, in order to be "protective." In the diagram on the opposite page we have graphically presented the average duties collected each year, under each tariff, from 1890 to 1920. At the top of the page is given the name of each successive tariff. The space covered by each is indicated by a heavy black line. The reader naturally looks at once for those Democratic, "free trade" Tariffs he has been hearing about all his Hfe. They have always been given in the plural, as if there was quite a bunch of them. Over and over again we have been told; "Whenever we have Democratic Tariffs we always have panics." He knows that panics, strikes, labor wars, "hard times" and in- dustrial depressions have constituted a good part of our past history. And so expects to see numerous "free trade" Tariffs. But he looks in vain. THE TARIFF LINE IS UNBROKEN. Where are they? In what years were they passed? They do not exist. They never did exist. All this talk about them, which fills up so large a part of the Congressional Record, is simply the expression of ignorance and du- plicity — the vaporings and deceptions of the demagog. The whole record is before you. There is in it one Democratic Tariff, and only one. Extend the period back from 1913 to 1860, and you still have but the one Demo- cratic Tariff— from 1894 to 1897. Thus were 50 years out of the 53 covered by Republican Tariffs — up to the Underwood Tariff of 1913. While there was but one Democratic Tariff in all that time, there was no "free trade" Tariff. In fact the phrase, a Free Trade Tariff, is such a contradiction of words as only a Protectionist would make. There can be no such thing as Free Trade, so long as there are such stupid and bar- barous things as Tariffs. And for the reason that there can be no such thing as Free Trade as long as the products of Trade are taxed! The blessings of Free Trade can come only when the extortions, plunder and oppression of all Tariff Walls have been swept from the earth. And this is possible only when all government revenues are raised by some fair and equitable system of Direct Taxation. There was a time when nearly the whole of our Government's revenues were raised by Tariffs. In 1921, only one dollar in every 14 was so raised! In every Tariff Bill there are two classes of goods: dutiable and free — those which must pay a Tariff Tax, and those which are allowed by Congress to enter free. In the diagram opposite, the top line represents the average rates on dutiable goods. It is perhaps the more important of the two. The lower line represents the combined rates on both free and dutiable. The lower line must be read ten points below that shown on the chart. Beginning with 1899, the whole trend is downward, even under High Tariffs, being only 16 % in 1920. The combined rate that year was only 6 %. The proportions of Foreign Goods coming in "free" under the various tariffs are as follows: McKinley, 53.4%; Cleveland, 49.5%; Dingley, 45.2%; Payne-Aldrich, 52.4%; Underwood, 67.2%.— These are the general facts as to Tariff Rates as shown by Custom House Reports. The reader must study the chart and make any further com- parisons and deductions for himself. 96 TARIFF PRIMER 25 LEADING ARTICLES EXPORTED. 23 OF WHICH ARE ALSO IMPORTED Exported Imported Cotton /Raw $t,136.408.Q16 | 138.743.702 \Manufactured 402.041.277 137,431.814 Iron and Steel 1,1 12.835.237 50.305.603 Breadstuflfs 1.079.107.701 125.345.323 Oils 609.671.471 181.815.871 Meat and Dairy Products 544,074.060 64.374.457 Veiiiclea 382.207.667 2.901.465 Coal and Coke 359,805,006 7,394,686 Tobacco 288,693.799 98.562.015 Leather 190,318,659 36,333,838 Woods 186,502.152 209,031,235 Chemicals, Drugs, etc 168,999,706 211,628,099 Copper 133,508,675 90,018.689 Electrical Machinery. Appliances, etc 101,990,004 (none) Sugar (Refined) 94,877,045 1,015.188.479 Paper 89.072 289 84.686,652 India Rubber 85,436,897 250.334,174 Fruits and Nuts 84,390,424 116,221,857 Explosives 56,845,689 1.377,176 Wool (Raw 4,936,740 126,972.088 \Manufactured 44,571,002 58,115.537 Agricultural Implements 46,277,638 5,716,573 Fertilizers 36,555.812 51,153.989 Naval Stores (Tar. Pitch and Turpentine) 34.503,389 (none) Furs and Fur Skins 32 886,995 93,558 940 Vegetables 32,784.416 50.420,326 Paraffine 32.619,318 820,885 FORDNEY TARIFF AT WORK The following table taken from the New York American, Oct. 8. 1922, shows how prices have started upward, under the Chemical Schedule, in less than three weeks after the tigning of the bill. The same thing ia taking place under other schedules. (per hundred pounds unless otherwise stated) Before After Barium Chloride (per ton) $85.00 $100.00 Carbonate of Potash 5.00 6.00 Caustic Potash 5.60 6.50 Acetic Acid (28%) 26.70 32.20 Alcohol, wood (per gallon) ,. .62 .72 Glycerine 17.50 18.00 White Lead 7.75 8.00 Formaldehyde 9.00 10.50 Acetone 14.00 17.00 Bleach 1.75 2.00 Citric Acid 45.00 50.00 Cocaine hydrochloride (per ounce) 6.25 7.25 Menthol (per pound) 6.00 6.25 Camphor 83.00 86.00 WOOL PRICES FROM 1880 TO 1921 (in cents per pound) 1880 ... 55 1890. 1881 ... .49 1891, 1882 ... .46 1892 1883 ... .42 1893 1884 ... .40 1894 1885 ... .33 1895 1886 ... .36 1896. 1887 ... .38 1897. 1888 ... .35 1898. 1889 ... .38 1899. 1900 .37 1901 ... .2» 1912 ... 32 .37 1902 ... .26 1913 36 .35 1903 . . . .31 1914 30 .33 1904 . . . .32 1915 36 .24 1905 ... .35 1916 45 .20 1906 . . . .38 1917 57 .31 1907 . . . .39 1918 90 .21 1908 . . . .38 1919 92 .30 1909 ... .38 1920 .... 1.12 .29 1910 ... .40 1921 . . . . 54 .30 1911 ... .34 Payne- Aldrick, Underwood and Fordney Tariffs 97 PAYNE-ALDRICH, UNDERWOOD AND FORDNEY TARIFFS In order to get a comparative view of the tariff rates in the last three Tariffs, I shall present the contrasts and reductions made by the Underwood Tariff to the rates in the Payne-Aldrich Tariff, as stated by Senator Under- wood on the day he introduced his bill in the House — April 23,1913 — and which comparisons were undenied thruout the debate. Mr. Underwood said: "Now, I would like the gentlemen on that side of the House (the Repub- lican side,) who have maintained this indefensible system of taxing the poor for five decades, to listen to the other side of the story. On common soap you placed a tax of 20%. We have lowered the tax to 5%. "You taxed the furniture of the poor man's house 35%. We have lowered it to 15%. "You taxed bread and biscuit 20%. We place them on the Free List. "On cotton clothing you taxed the people of this country 50 %. We have reduced it to 30%. "On the flannels that protect them against the cold winter storms you taxed the people of the United States over 93%. We have reduced the tax to 25% and 35%. "The tax on women's and children's dress goods under your system of levying a tax for the benefit of the manufacturer, was about 100%. We have lowered that to 35%. "You taxed the shoes of the people of the United States, after giving the shoemaker free raw material — and stating at the time you gave it that he did not need the protection — you gave him 10% and we give free shoes to the people of America. "On the entire chemical schedule the tax was 25.91 %. Our taxes levied on that schedule was 19.64%, or a reduction in the chemical schedule of 24% below the Payne law. "On earths, earthenware and glass ware, you levied a tax of about 51%. We levy a tax of 33%, a reduction below the Payne Bill of 35%. "On metals and manufactures of metals, you levied a tax of 34%. We levy a tax of 20%, a reduction below the Payne Bill of 41%. "On wood and the manufactures of wood, you levied a tax of 12% and we leA^ a tax of 3}4%, a reduction of 71%. We place most of it on the free list, in order that American workmen may have lumber with which to build their own homes. "You have levied a tax on sugar of 48%. We have reduced that tax to 35% for the next three years, or a reduction of 25%; and at the end of the three years we intend, if this bill becomes a law, TO PLACE IT ON THE FREE LIST. So that the one commodity above all others that most directly reflects the taxes levied at the custom house no longer goes on the table of the consumer bearing the marks of 50 YEARS OF OPPRESSIVE TAXATION that our friends on that side of the House have taught the American consuming public to realize when they open their home door. "As to tobacco and the manufactures thereof, we consider them as lux- uries, or in the nature of luxuries, and good revenue producers, and so made no vital changes in the schedule. 98 TARIFF PRIMER "On agricultural products and provisions we have reduced the tax from 29% to 17%, a reduction of 42%. "On spirits, wines, and other beverages we have left the taxes as they are in the present law. "On cotton manufactures you taxed the public about 46%. We reduced the average tax to 30%, making a reduction of 33% below the Payne Bill. "On flax, hemp and jute and their manufactures we have reduced the tax from 45% to 26%, a reduction of 42% below the Payne Bill. (Flax, hemp and tow were afterwards put on the Free List.) "On wool and manufactures of wool, you taxed the public nearly 56%. We tax them 183^%, a reduction in favor of the American people of 67% below the Payne Bill. "On silk goods the tax was about 52%. We tax it 44%, or a reduction of 15%. "On paper and books you taxed them 21%. We tax them 12%, or a re- duction of 45%." The following quotation, from the Literary Digest — Sept. 2, 1922 — shows the increase in rates made by the Fordney-McCumber Tariff over the rates in the Underwood Tariff: "The new tariff bill, the New York Evening Post (Ind.) has said, 'makes the free breakfast table a mockery,' and in this paper Mr. William O. Scroggs, the economist, recently recounted 'the short and simple but somewhat intimate annals of a morning hour in the life of a plain middle- class American consumer,' to 'see how the tariff penetrates into the inner temple of his existence.' To quote from this story as amended by Mr. Scroggs to fit the final form of the Senate Bill: " 'His day begins when he is aroused by an alarm clock, and the new tariff bill raises the duty on this article 67 per cent. His first act is to throw off the bed-covering, on which the duty has been increased 60 per cent. He jumps from his bed, on which the duty is advanced 133%, and dons a summer bathrobe, with the duty up 60 per cent., and slippers, with the duty increased 33 per cent. 'He walks over a Brussels carpet (duty up 100 per cent.) to close the win- dow, the duty on the pane of which has been raised 33 per cent., and adjusts the shade (duty up 20 per cent-.) and curtains (up 50 per cent.). Then he enters the bathroom, stands before a mirror, on which the duty has been raised 100 per cent., sets out his shaving-stick, subject to an increase in duty of 67 per cent., his shaving-brush (duty up 30 per cent.), and razor (up 100 per cent.), and begins his tonsorial operations. This over, he devotes his attention to the bathtub, on which the duty has been raised 100 per cent. Towels (with the duty up 60 per cent.), soap (up 67 per cent.), tooth-brush and hair-brush (up 30 per cent, each), and comb (up 67 per cent.) are next in demand. 'As our comsumer dresses, it may be noted that the new bill increases the duty 60 per cent, on his underwear, 33 per cent, on his hose, 15 per cent, on his shirt and collar, 20 per cent, or more on his necktie, and 60 per cent, on his suit of clothes. 'Our consumer decides to discard his waistcoat and transfers fountain-pen (up 100 per cent.), penknife (up 200 per cent.), and lead pencil (up 80 per cent.) from waistcoat to coat-pockets, picks a fresh linen handkerchief (up Payne-Aldrich, Underwood and Fordney Tariffs 99 30 per cent.) from the dresser (up 133 per cent.), polishes his eyeglasses (up 15 per cent.), and after giving his clothes a touch with a brush (up 57 per cent.), is ready for breakfast. *At the breakfast-table our consumer spreads a napkin (duty up 15 per cent.) on his knees, and turns on the current for his electric toaster, on which the duty has been advanced 160 per cent. He drinks water from a glass, on which the duty is 45 per cent, higher, and begins his breakfast with an apple (duty up 200 per cent.) baked with sugar (duty up 84 per cent.) in an aluminum dish (up 150 per cent.) on a cast-iron stove (duty up 100 per cent.) 'The duty is also advanced 27 per cent, on his chinaware, 20 per cent, on his table silverware, 200 per cent, on his oatmeal, and 225 per cent, on his butter. The cream for his coffee has been removed from the free list and subjected to a duty of 22 H cents a gallon, and his eggs also have been taken from the free hst and made dutiable at 8 cents per dozen. The salt for his eggs likewise comes off the free list, and so does his bacon and the flour that goes into his bread. Even the duty on the salt-shaker gets a boost of 45 per cent. 'The only things on his table that have not been subjected to a higher tariff duty are his coffee and his drinking-water.' " 100 TARIFF PRIMER THE SCRAMBLE BEGINS FOR STILL HIGHER RATES The Fordney-McCumber Tariff did not settle tariff rates. It just unsettled them. No one can tell what the tariff rates will be on a single article — except dyes — three months ahead. This for the reason that the Fordney Tariff gave to the President the unparalleled power to raise or lower the rates on any product 50%. It did more. It gave him the power also to change the present basis of Foreign Valuation, to American Valuation. In making this shift alone — without adding additional tariff — he can often change rates fully 60%, and in some cases, 100%. As showing the workings of this unprecedented, and probably unconsti- tutional, procedure, I will give clippings from an article I find in the New York World, just as the book is going to the printer's: TARIFF GLUTTONS HUNGER FOR MORE {Special to the N. Y. World) WASHINGTON, Oct. 12.— Seekers of still further tariff bounties already are pressing the United States Tariff Commission to take advantage of new provisions of the Fordney-McCumber act whereby the President is allowed to jack up rates by 50 per cent., if he deems it necessary, in order to "equalize production costs here and abroad." Upward of fifty notices have been entered with the commission so far by beneficiaries of the new tariff who want additional concessions that will shut foreign goods out of the American market and thereby permit of higher prices for domestic articles. Many verbal communications also have come in. The commission inteiprets this early stream of applications to mean an ensuing fioodtide that not only will swamp the commission with work but necessitate at least a doubling of its expenses. Woolen, cotton, steel, chemical and other manufactuiers are among these first applicants for bigger benefits at once, not being satisfied with the already unpreiedenledly high tariff rates. The ne'v^ law specifies that the Commission must hold hearings on these applications and then determine the actual difference between the cost of production heie and abroad. According to veteran experts of the commis- sion, this is impossible, to begin with, since production costs not only are fluctuating rapidly because of present unsettled economic conditions, but foreign manufacturers both resent and forbid such prying into their secrets. Although the commission is, in theory, an impartial judicial body, its members are not blind to the tremendous political power which the Fordney- McCumber bill confers on the President; and since the clarnor for readjust- ment by Presidential proclamation already has started, reinforced by poli- tical pressure, expectations are that the commission will find itself FORCED INTO APPROVING CONSTANT INCREASES, OR ELSE HAVING ITS RECOMMENDATIONS OVERRULED." UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY AA 001 120 501