^^.v' ■ S ^■-^V, t^ '. 'vna,'^ Te?w LIBRARY OF THE UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA. A PROTECTION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES Edited by William Harbutt Dawson GERMANY PROTECTION IN GERMANY A HISTORY OF GERMAN FISCAL POLICY DURING THE NINETEENTH CENTURY BY WILLIAM HARBUTT DAWSON Author of " German Socialism and Ferdinand Lassalle," " Prince Bismarck and State Socialism," " Germany and the Germans," Etc. '^^^O- iH£ I U^4•.VS-.«S5T '■^^^A; LONDON: P. S. KING & SON ORCHARD HOUSE WESTMINSTER 1904. BRADBURY, AGNEW, & CO. LD., PRINTERS, LONDON AND TONBRIDGE. I PREFATORY NOTE. That history should be written without tendency is a sound and just maxim. But when a tendency is implicit in history, it is a dishonest affectation of impartiality to omit to bring that tendency to light. CONTENTS. CHAP. I. THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION II. THE ZOLLVEREIN .... III. THE REACTION .... IV. PRINCE Bismarck's theories of taxation V. the tariff of 1879 VI. the supplementary tariffs "Wii. the commercial treaty era VIII. the agrarian movement IX. THE tariff of I902 X. PROTECTION AND TRADE . XI. THE CONDITION OF THE WORKING MAN XII. AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION . XIII. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER XIV. PROTECTION AND TAXATION 17 26 41 58 78 98 128 141 161 185 202 224 239 INDEX 257 f UNiV.- PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER I. THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. A REVIEW of fiscal policy in Germany must begin with the statement that protective laws in the interest of industry and agriculture have been the tradition of the States which form the present Empire. Freedom of trade has been the exception, and when it has occurred it has been a temporary lapse from continuity and custom. This is not a proposition to be argued, but an affirmation of fact, the recognition of which is necessary to the right understanding of all that follows. But this fundamental fact, that Protection is the tradition of German policy, implies that from an early period there was a trade to protect, hence that Germany's commercial development is by no means so modern as it is commonly supposed to be. Writing of that country in the middle of the fifteenth century, the Papal Legate -^Eneas Sylvius said : " If this mass of great towns and territories, with their population and their wealth, were united in one purpose, what an empire and a P.G. B 2 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. people the Germans would be ! " " In the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries," says a German writer, " Germany was unquestionably esteemed as very rich in comparison with the other countries of Europe, and it became so principally through mining and trade. The seat of her great com- merce was in the North, though in the towns of the South, too, an important and prosperous industry was developed, thanks especially to their ties with Italy, whose industries were so famous at that time." But the industry and trade which had been built up under the fostering care of guild and merchant at home, and by Hanseatic enterprise abroad, fell into decay during the Thirty Years' War of the seventeenth century. When the Peace of Westphalia ended the strife in 1648 the desolation remained. Town and country alike were depopulated; the national resources had been deplenished ; the working classes had to learn their arts and trades over again ; the entire economic life of the nation was disordered and paralysed. Thus before the war began there were in Berlin and Kolln (old Berlin) 1,236 inhabited dwellings, but in 1653 (three years after the peace) 1,052 ; in Brandenburg the number fell from 1,144 to 554, in Frankfort-on-the-Oder from 1,029 ^o 523, in Potsdam from 191 to loi, in Rathenow from 299 to 153, and in Mittenwalde from 245 to nil. Once German merchants had controlled the markets of Russia and Norwa}^ but during those terrible years of unrest and demoralisation that position of THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. 3 primacy had been forfeited ; their privileges were withdrawn ; their goods were refused admission to the wonted markets. Abroad as at home the fruits of generations of effort were sacrificed. In Prussia the economic regeneration was stimulated by artificial immigration from Holland and France. It is estimated that in 1786 not less than one-third of all the inhabitants of the monarchy were either immigrants or descendants of immigrants. Many names of towns and villages in the western provinces still com- memorate this admission and assimilation of a foreign element which was then invaluable. If ever Prussian autocracy justified itself it was during the reign of Frederick the Great, between 1740 and 1786, years which saw a vast economic revival and expansion in all parts of the young kingdom. His theory of State policy was that of his age, the Mercantilism of Colbert, with its political ideal of a self-contained State. Hence Frederick erected barriers around his frontiers for the purpose of preventing, and not merely of' restricting, the import of foreign commodities, yet with unsuspected inconsequence armed his own manufacturers and merchants for the in- vasion of the foreigner's preserves by the gift of export premiums, well satisfied that the natural wealth of his dearly consolidated kingdom should be exchanged for gold and silver from abroad. It was the age of the balance of trade. His edicts went so far as to roundly forbid the introduction B 2 4 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of every class of goods which could be produced at home, even if less cheaply and of inferior quality, and where total prohibition was relaxed he imposed hi.^h duties, so that the State coffers might benefit side by side with native enterprise. On the other hand, the exportation of raw material was forbidden in the interest of cheap production, for so much of economic insight he possessed, in spite of his Mercantilistic fallacies, as to know it to be sounder policy to send abroad manufactured goods than raw material, since in the former case the foreigner exchanged his own products to a larger extent for labour, and by purchasing that labour maintained the strength and life behind it. So far did he carry this principle of productive independence that he imported silk- worms into the country, so that silk need not be purchased from abroad. By subsidy, too, new industries were estab- lished, and old industries which languished were encouraged. If the foreigner's goods were' not desired, the foreigner himself was welcomed, so ,'he brought manufacturing skill and knowledge into the land. The State was ever ready with liberal gifts and temporary loans for the purchase of raw material, for the establishment of technical instruction, and for the introduction of foreign teachers. The sums which Frederick gave in these and other ways for the promotion of industries made an aggregate which was indeed enormous for an age characterised by State THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. 5 bounty so less spacious than our own. In 1783 he granted 260,000 thalers in one sum for the improvement of the Prussian mines and smelting works. It was also his idea that the town was the town and the country the country, and that never the twain should blend. While industry was natural and good in the former, it was incongruous in the latter : hence all enter- prise of the kind was forbidden on the land, and the " garden city " was reserved for a later age. Agriculture he no less supported in every suit- able way. The great landowners he checked with a firm hand ; the small peasant proprietors he encouraged to ways of enterprise and thrift ; the condition of the serfs he ameliorated in the rough spirit of an age to which the ideas of liberty, equality, and fraternity were still alien. " The endeavours of Frederick the Great to improve the economic condition of Prussia," writes Adolf Beer, " cannot be sufficiently estimated, even though one may not agree with the fundamental ideas by which he was led. He gave equal attention to trade, industry, and agriculture. By inducing foreigners to settle down in various provinces he sought to give to agriculture the labour required in the draining of marshy districts and tlie cultivation of waste lands. Numerous decrees prove the care with which the King promoted agri- cultural interests ; better methods came into applica- tion, and the instruction given to the peasants at the command of the King had very successful results. Worthy of all admiration is the energy of the King, who repeatedly enjoined his subjects to plant vacant lands with fruit trees, to lay out hop-gardens, and to cultivate the vine, llax, madder, woad, carraway seed, 6 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. anise seed, &c. It was, however, a great evil that, owing to the opposition of the nobility, the King was not able to abolish serfage, hereditary servitude, &c., and that he had to be satisfied with the amelioration of the peasants' oppressed condition." ^ Simultaneously many of the ancient restrictions, like the Guild system, which had acted in restraint of trade, were relaxed; roads and canals were built ; the system of inland excise taxes was simplified and alleviated ; better means of letter conveyance were introduced. Foreign trade enterprises were similarly encouraged. As early as 1750 the Asiatic Trading Company was formed, by Frederick's help, at Emden for the promotion of the export trade ; and to the same patronage was due the Maritime Trading Company {Seehandlungscoiii- pagnie), founded in Berlin in 1772 for the same purpose. Nearly a hundred years before this, how- ever, the African Trading Company {Afrikanische Handelsgesellschaft), an undertaking half mercantile and half colonial, had been formed (in 1682) by a band of merchant adventurers desirous of exploit- ing the resources of the Guinea Coast.^ Jn. the interest of foreign trade Frederick also concluded "^ commercial treaties with Russia, with Holland, with Poland, with Turkey, and North America. If the Prussian monarchy lost ground between 1786 and the Emancipatory Edicts of the ' " Allgemeine Geschichte des Welthandels." - In his " Deutsche Colonialgeschichte " Max von Koschitzky, with the characteristic thoroughness of his nation, traces German Colonial endeavours back to the tenth century. THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION, 7 Stein-Hardenberg period, the decline must be attributed in part, of course, to the poHtical troubles of the period, but also, and in a large degree, to the untoward fate which placed the destinies of the country for eleven fateful years in the hands of the weakest member oftheHohenzollern race, Frederick William II., years which saw the abandonment of a great and salutary tradition, and were no longer marked by that ardent and unwearying solicitude of the Crown for the economic welfare of the nation which was so important a feature of Frederick the Great's strong if arbitrary rule. The Prussian linen, woollen, cotton, silk, leather, and sugar manufactures, the mining and mineral industries, the trades in metals, both precious and base, all go back to the eighteenth century or earlier, and even then they had a con- siderable export. In 1781 Prussia sold manufac- tures to the value of 25 million thalers, in 1785 to the value of 30 million thalers, in 1793 to the value of 37 millions, and it is computed that one-half went abroad. Her pig-iron production was 15,145 tons in 1798, and by 1824 it was only 35,813 tons. In the year 1795-96 Prussia had the following exchange of metals : — Iron in bars . . . Steel ... Iron plate ... Iron and brass ware Rough iron ware Imports. Exports. Thalers. Thalers. 312,828 259,287 213,411 200,866 158,102 160,042 29.792 35,815 360,666 569,632 8 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. a total import value of 1,074,799 thalers, against an export value of 1,225,642 thalers, giving the desired " balance of trade " of 150,843 thalers. In 1802 Prussia's metal workers numbered 10,719 persons, for the most part engaged in iron. At the beginning of last century Prussia was still an agricultural State : 80 per cent, of its inhabitants followed pastoral occupations of one kind or another. Hence not only did the country produce corn enough for its own use, but it was able to export freely. Manufactures were in the main confined to the West, to Silesia, and to Berlin and Magdeburg, while its most flourishing ports were Memel, Danzig, Konigsberg and Emden. The practice of exclusive trading was as before carried on to the utmost, and the inter- change of merchandise, not only between State and State but even within the boundaries of the same political territory, was impeded by a gro- tesque system of duties and dues. The combined effect of these hindrances to intercourse was ruinous. '* The principles of the Mercantilistic system," sa3'S a German writer, in reference to this period, " had paralysed trade. The embargo system extended even to the internal parts of the monarchy. A province, even a district, regarded its neighbour as foreign, and every locality had its own duties and its special tariffs. Foreign imports were prohibited, but as it was impossible to do without the better and much cheaper English and French cotton and silk goods, THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. 9 a large smuggling trade was carried on everywhere, which defied the severest legal measures. Such was the condition of Prussia before 1806."^ And of the social effects of this short-sighted and ex- hausting fiscal policy in Prussia especially, King Frederick William III. himself said: — " When I reflect that, as experience has always proved, the principal revenues of the State, and those most suited to its needs, can only be raised on the primary needs of life and the commonest articles of trade, and that the number of those articles is very limited, I am shocked at the voluminous excise and customs tariffs." It was the laws and regulations prompted by the wise statesmanship of Stein and Hardenberg that gave to Prussia the relief which its economic life needed by removing the fetters upon industry, handicraft, and trade, and making possible for the first time the full exercise of its productive powers. It would lead us too far to review in detail the policy inaugurated by these sagacious men, who were as great in practical knowledge as in ideas, as great in administrative genius as in patriotism, and this is the less necessary since the late Professor Seeley's exhaustive work on Stein is accessible to those who desire to follow up the subject more minutely. Of the two men Hardenberg may be regarded as by preference the thinker, the theorist, Stein as the doer, the practitioner ; but both were alike in proceeding from the supposition that 1 " Die ueuere Nationalokonomie," Moritz Meyer, 1881. 10 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. greater liberty in every direction was Prussia's need and the key to her regeneration. Hardenberg boldly called for the application of " democratic principles in a'monarchical Government," for "a revolution in a good sense." In his Memorial {Denkschrift) of September 12, 1807, on " the re- organisation of the State," he avowed the desire to give to the State and the nation the greatest possible amount of freedom — in thought, in speech, in action, in trade, in industry, in government. He did not propose to abandon protective laws alto- gether ; but, while contending for free imports as far as practicable, he was willing to retain such moderate duties as would not impede trade where the conditions of industry seemed to require them. Nor did he abandon the idea that the future of Prussia was bound up with the continued prosperity of agriculture. " I am quite convinced," he wrote, " that we have sacrificed the benefits of trade, which for the greater part, and in Prussia particu- larly, is derived from agriculture, to the factory system, to the clear disadvantage of the State." If Hardenberg was in favour of fundamental reforms, so also was Stein, though his was a greater caution. Of the two he was unquestionably the more solid economist. He had studied at Gottingen, par excellence the school of the cameral sciences in those days, and while a follower of Adam Smith, he sought to apply Liberalistic ideas, not on any slavish model, but according to the special needs of Prussia. One of his first official THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. ii acts was the foundation of the Prussian Statistical Bureau in 1805, the year after he became Minister of Agriculture and Commerce. Greater liberty was Stein's watchword. The " Instruction to the Royal Governments of the Prussian Provinces " of December 26, 1808, after emphasising the principle that industry must be free and no man must be restricted in the choice of a calling proceeded : — t>' "Together with this liberty, facility of communica- tion and freedom of trade both at home and abroad are also necessary if our industry, trade, and welfare are to thrive. Thus those industries will naturally come into being which can be carried on to the best advantage, and which are the most suited to the economic condition of the countrv and the civilisation of the nation. It is a mistake to believe that it is advantageous to a State to produce itself articles which can be bought more cheaply abroad. The increased costs of production caused by manufacturing them are an absolute loss, and had they been employed in another industry would have given abundant gain. It is a distorted view that one should in such a case seek to keep the money in the country, and rather not buy at all. ... It is not necessary to favour trade ; it must simply not be obstructed. Freedom of trade and of industry creates the greatest possible competi- tion between the producing and consuming public, and protects the consumers most effectively against scarcity and excessive prices." That was the theory of Stein's economic posi- tion. In practice he departed from it, like a wise statesman, just as interest and policy dictated. Thus while he introduced a low tariff of import 12 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. duties, he continued to prohibit the export of raw wool in the interest of Silesia. While he advo- cated the free import of corn on principle, he held that the condition of agriculture must determine whether it were safe to apply the good principle in reality, and this reservation stayed his hand. Having first strengthened the foundations of civil and political life by legislation reforming the land laws and provincial and local administration, he promptly turned to economic and fiscal ques- tions. The law of October 28, 1810, for the unification of the customs system provided that henceforth excise should be levied on but twenty commodities ; the tax was made uniform in all the provinces ; and octrois were abolished. Thus from the second decade of the nineteenth century the direct State encouragement of industry and trade ceased for a long time. Rightly or wrongly, it was deemed to be incompatible with the new theories of economic freedom and inde- pendence. So long as the State had exercised the right to control the movements of its citizens b}^ restrictions upon the choice of trade and occu- pation, upon migration and residence, it recognised the counter obligation to act in something like a parental relationship towards every class of the community. When, however, the restrictions were thrown off, the State's direct patronage was forfeited as well. There was less prohibition of exports and imports, but there were also no more bounties and subventions. There was gain and THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. 13 there was loss ; and in the end the gain probably proved the greater, though while the transition lasted the pressure of the discipline was often more obvious than its beneficial effects. At that time Prussia had two tariffs — one for the agri- cultural East of the monarchy, devised to meet its special economic conditions and sufficiently protective, and the other for the more industrial West, marked by lower duties. These duties were twofold. There was an import duty proper, levied on the gross weight of the goods brought over the frontier, and there was an excise levied on the net weight of goods which were destined to remain in the country. It is interesting to notice how freedom broadened down from precedent to precedent. The reforming work of Stein was continued in his spirit by Count von Biilow, as Finance Minister, who did away the last of the old prohibitions. The first project of law was one of January 7, 1817, intended to readjust both customs and excise, and it was one of the first duties of the Council of State {Staatsrath) called into being by Frederick William III. in March, 1817, to deliberate upon this measure, which was referred to a committee of twenty-four members, whose president was Wilhelm von Humboldt. Billow's idea was on the one hand to simplify internal taxation by abolishing a majority of the excise duties, which at that time fell upon an enormous number of articles, and to confine them to a tcw remunerative 14 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. imports, and on the other hand to facilitate foreign trade by the introduction of a rational tariff. While, however, very low duties were to be imposed upon goods which were either not produced in Prussia or were not likely to create serious competition, upon articles of luxury a high tax was levied for revenue purposes : upon tea, coffee, sugar, as much as 30 per cent. The excise proposals were rejected, though the customs tariff was approved, and it is notable that one reason for the former step was the objection that the suggested tax on meat and flour would press heavily on the food of the poor. The whole scheme had to be withdrawn for revision. A better fate awaited its successor, which became the law of May 26, 1818, " on the customs and excise duties on foreign goods and on trade between the provinces of the State," a law which intro- duced a great measure of freedom of trade and made of Prussia a fiscal unity. It provided that foreign products might be imported into the country and home products be exported, the former to be subjected to a moderate duty, which in general amounted to half a thaler per cent., and some also to an excise tax not exceeding 10 per cent, ad valorem, though less where home industry was not injured. " The duties," the Edict ran, " shall protect home industry b}' a suitable taxation of foreign trade and the consumption of foreign goods, and shall secure to the State such a THE PRUSSIAN TRADITION. 15 revenue as may be possible without impediment to trade." It was against the Free Trade tendency that was thus gaining ground that Friedrich List's " German Commercial and Industrial Association " {Deutscher Handels- iiitd Gewerbeverein) was established in 1819, with its policy of unrestricted commercial inter- course within the State, but a customs system on the frontiers. Theoretically, List was himself a Free Trader, though he regarded the doctrine of Adam Smith as a counsel of perfection, and pend- ing mankind's greater maturity, he was concerned that Germany should confine attention to her own interests, and leave other countries to work out their economic salvation in their own way. List suspected that by her new law Prussia was making history too fast. There can be little doubt that it was this freer industrial movement and this freer mercantile intercourse which regenerated the economic life of the country, depressed and disordered as it was by the exhausting wars of the end of the eighteenth and the beginning of the nineteenth century. Those were times of invincible hopes and pathetic assurances. A Cabinet Order issued by Frederick William III. from Carlsbad, August i, 1817, declared that the principle of the free import of foreign manufactures, in return for a comparatively small duty, should be the basis of the legislation of the Prussian State " for all future time." Such legislation for perpetuity was beyond the power even i6 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of an absolute Sovereign. The time of reaction came, of course, when the work of Stein, Harden- berg, and Biilow was in part impugned and undone, but it is not less idle than ungrateful to pretend that men like these and the many advisers who helped in the realisation of their ideas — Niebuhr, von Altenstein, Dolma, Schon, Wilhelm von Humboldt, Scharnhorst, Gneisenau — were the fools which by implication they are often made out to be by sages after the event. The policy whose culmination and crown was the law of 1818 was that William Huskisson lauded in our own House of Commons in 1825, ending with the expression of a pious hope that "the time would come when England would follow Prussia's example." THE ZOLLVEREIN. 17 CHAPTER n. THE ZOLLVEREIN. Another and still more important period in the history of German fiscal policy is marked by the Zollverein in which most of the States of the Empire were one by one drawn together for com- mercial and customs purposes on the basis of the Prussian law of 1818. The fiscal arrangements of the old Empire were the embodiment of chaos. Not only did every State fight its neighbours with duties of everv kind, but within its own borders an ill-conceived system of excises and dues made the interchange of commodities as difficult as possible. There were imposts by land and imposts by water ; there were octrois at every town gate, with dues on sales and dues on purchases ; and the mischief which this melange of fiscal absurdities left undone was completed by the monopolies exercised by Governments and the privileges conferred upon corporations and private persons. In 1817 the first serious attempt to introduce freedom of trade within the whole Empire was made in a proposal brought forward in the Federal Diet {Bundestag) by the representative of Wiirtemberg. While, however, the cause of fiscal unity owed much to the enlightened Sovereign of that kingdom, P.G, c iS PROTECTION IN GERMANY. William I., the inspiration which carried the movement forward came unquestionably from Prussia. Between 1819 and 1823 the States of Schwarzburg and Anhalt adopted the Prussian tariff by treaty, and amalgamated with her for customs and excise purposes. In 1828 the Grand Duchy of Hesse joined the combination, in 1831 Hesse-Cassel followed, and in 1833 Bavaria and Wiirtemberg (the last two already joined with Hohenzollern in a customs and commercial union of their own since 1828), whose adhesion made certain its eventual extension to the rest of the Empire. But the Zollverein, whose motto was " Freedom of Trade through Unity " {Handels- freiheit dutch Eintracht), was hailed by the Imperialists of that day as more than a victory for the arts of peace and for rational methods of taxation ; it was regarded, as indeed it proved, as an important step on the way to political federa- tion. " A new era in national life begins," writes the Prussian bureaucrat Stengel in a quaint tractate of 1835 iiow before me : ^ " The larger part of Germany, closely united by the great German Customs and Commercial Union, sees its industry freed from the fetters which heretofore impeded internal trade — the most important for all peoples — and by means of an extensive territorial organisation is protected, by a moderate customs 1 " Von dem auslandischen Handel und der Seemacht deutscher Stadte im Mittelalter und von den finanziellen Verhiiltnissen des jetzigen deutschen Zollvereins." (Pots- dam, 1835.) \ UM THE ZOLLVEREIN. 19 system which, with wise caution, does not exclude all foreign competition, from the trade of those nations that, thanks to a selfish commercial policy, refuse admission to German manufactures altogether, and only admit German produce to the very smallest extent. The German peoples . . . are now by community of material interests, that important basis of a common national life, united more closely than ever before, and in such a manner that as a result the strengthening of the wider German Confederation may likewise be anticipated in time of danger. . . ." — The Customs Union, which now comprised eighteen States, with an area of 7,719 square miles, and a population of 23,000,000, was first concluded for eight years. Before those years had expired there had been added to it Hesse- Homburg, Baden, and Nassau in 1835, Frankfurt in 1836, Waldeck in 1838, and Brunswick, Lippe, and Luxemburg in 1842 ; while Hanover and Oldenburg follow'ed in 185 1 and 1852 respectively, and between 1854 and 1865 the whole of the States of the Empire save Austria, the Mecklen- burgs, and the Hanse Cities belonged to the federation, customs duties being levied on the common account, and being divided amongst the contracting States according to population. Of the Zollverein it need only be said further that its renewal in 1865 was the last that was needed, for its work was well nigh done. In 1867, by treaty between the North German Confederation and the South German States (Bavaria, Wiirtemberg, Baden and Hesse), a new Customs Union was con- cluded, with a Parliament armed with legislative c 2 20 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. power in customs matters, for a period of twelve years. Two years later the customs laws and ordinances of the Union were modified, and they passed into the legislation of the new Empire, and became substantially the basis of the fiscal system which lasted until 1879. In the interval the tariff basis had been modified from time to time. Under the tariff of 1818 the duties on grain had been, per bushel : Wheat, 1 1 silver groschen or nearly 2d. ; rye and barley, |- silver groschen ; oats and buckwheat, ^ silver groschen. In 1824 the duties were fixed at 5 silver groschen (6^.) on wheat for the Eastern provinces of Prussia, adjacent to corn-exporting Russia, and 2 silver groschen (2^^.) in the West ; and on other kinds of grain i silver groschen. In 1827 a uniform rate of 5 silver groschen was adopted for all Prussia. This rate lasted twenty- five years as the basis of the Zollverein, and under it agriculture developed greatly. There were other modifications. Thus in 1838 the Prussian provision stipulating for a minimum excise of ten per cent, was omitted, and in general a stronger protective tendency set in. In 1843 the duty on cigars and snuff was increased. In 1844 a duty on pig-iron was imposed for the first time, and some of the duties on iron manufactured goods were increased. In 1846 Protection was made severer, the duty on raw linen yarn, for example, being increased twelve-fold. In 1851 the cigar duty was again raised, and that on rice THE ZOLLVEREIN. 21 was reduced. Meantime England had gone over to Free Trade by the law of 1846, and the example of the first commercial country of the world was not lost upon German statesmen. In 1853 the duties on coffee, tea and wine were reduced. That , year also a more deliberate step was taken towards Free Trade, when, by the commercial treaty of February igth, Prussia and Austria agreed to levy no corn duties against each other. In 1856 the Verein tariff was further revised, the rates being reduced to 2 silver groschen for wheat, and ^ silver groschen for other kinds of corn. Thus Schaffle writes : — "Until the beginning of tlie 'sixties, under a largely \ bureaucratic treaty system of administration, the Zoll- verein maintained a commercial policy which, while moderately protective and fairly stable, yet slowly and cautiously aimed at freedom of trade." It was, however, the conclusion by Prussia in « 1862 of the treaty of commerce with France, which came into operation throughout the entire area of the Zollverein in 1865, that gave the greatest practical stimulus to the new movement. That treaty was not Prince Bismarck's idea, for he found it ready drawn up when he became Minister President in the autumn of 1862. It fell to Bismarck, however, to carry it through Parliament, and while it is true that the treaty belonged to the period of his official life when, as he frequently said in after years, his economic conscience was in the keeping of others, it is fair to add that the reasons 22 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. which influenced him were purely political. When the episode was mentioned during a discussion in the Reichstag, on February 21st, 1879, in proof of changed convictions, the Chancellor retorted that convictions had nothing to do with the matter, and frankly avowed that the treaty was meant to be a weapon for use against Austria, and did indeed keep France friendly on the Danish question. " In the further struggle with Austria which threat- ened in 1865, and which took place in 1866, the restraint of France would certainly not have con- tinued as far as the point which happily for us it was if I had not cultivated relationships with her in every way open to me." Whatever the immediate purpose of the French treaty, it unquestionably committed Germany to further progress on Free Trade lines, while its effects upon her foreign trade were very marked. "Bismarck," writes Schaffle, "was at that time at once the political guardian and the political favourite of the Free Trade party." The same year the tariff was again revised by a law of May ist, and a rescript of June 17th, which came into operation on July ist, and now in a decidedly liberal spirit. The duties on corn and flour, cattle and sheep, yarn of flax and hemp, and hand-spun stuffs were repealed altogether, while others were greatly reduced, among them the duties on butter and cheese, cotton yarn, cotton wadding, cotton and woollen goods, dress goods, linen, iron, steel, copper, zinc, tin and lead goods, glass and glass goods, leather and leather goods, THE ZOLLVEREIN. 23 silk and silk goods, paper, soap, coal, porcelain, earthenware, beer, wine, vinegar, cider, etc. Encouraged by the action of the Government the Free Trade party in commercial and scientific circles redoubled their efforts. At this time the manufacturers of West and South German}' were overwhelmingly Protectionist, while in the textile districts of Saxony the tendency was rather towards Free Trade. Even the agricultural societies of Saxony in 1848 petitioned the Frankfurt Parlia- ment against customs duties of every kind. Amongst publicists and in academic circles there had since 1848 been a vigorous Liberal school, whose leaders included John Prince Smith, who, though an Englishman by birth, settled in Ger- many, first as a teacher of languages, and won great influence there from the 'fifties onward, being elected both to the Prussian Diet and the Imperial Reichstag ; W. A. Lette, a high Prussian State official ; Max Wirth, honourably associated with the Trade Union movement; Otto Michaelis, an able economic writer and publicist, who ended his career in the Ministry of Finance; Schulze-Delitzsch, the founder of co-operation in Germany ; Julius Faucher, for some years a leader of the Progressive party in the Prussian Diet ; and others. At the instiga- tion of Prince Smith and Faucher, a Free Trade party was organised in Berlin, and its influence gradually extended from North Germany to other parts of the country. Prince Smith especially was 24 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. unwearied in the agitation which he carried on both by speech and writing on behalf of the economic theories which had just won so signal a triumph in England. He travelled a large part of the country as an apostle of the Free Trade gospel, imparting everywhere some at least of his own enthusiasm and conviction, organising societies, encouraging the establishment of literary sheets in the service of the new faith, and successfully identi- fying economic with political and Parliamentary Liberalism. Not only so, but, like all enthusiasts, he contended for the immediate introduction of unequivocal Free Trade, without half measures or compromise of any kind. To those who, only partially convinced of the unwisdom of a protective policy, pleaded for slow and cautious progress in the new direction, he replied that any dallying with Protection was a mere protraction of economic injury. It was, he quaintly said, like docking a dog's tail an inch a day, just to spare its feelings. To anticipate for a moment, so far did his temporary influence go, that at the beginning of the 'sixties he was able to convince some of the agricultural societies of West and East Prussia — later a hot-bed of extreme Protectionism and agrarianism — that their truest interest was a policy of free imports. It was not long before the heresy was recanted. Free Trade principles also found expression in the Economic Congress formed in 1858 by Lette, Wirth, Victor Bohmert, and Pickford, which first met at Gotha, and in the German Commercial Diet THE ZOLLVEREIN. 25 (Handelstng), an organisation of Chambers of Com- merce and Industry. Two 3'ears after the conclu- sion of the French treaty a determined effort was made to give the coup de grace to whatever Protec- tionist traditions still lingered in the Government. On August 27th, 1867, an influential congress of political economists and representatives of industry was held at Hamburg, and called for the immediate revision of the customs tariff in a Free Trade spirit. It was recommended that the tariff should hence- forth be restricted to a few articles chosen for their suitability as sources of revenue, that thus " by the abolition of the protective system larger resources might be secured to the community and the State, and more elbow-room be given for the economic activity of the individual." Industry especially should be relieved of all the duties which impeded it, while the revenue of the State should be increased by promoting the consumption of excisable commodities. Little now remained to complete the transition ^^ to Free Trade, and that little was done during the succeeding eight years. In 1868 the duties on wine were reduced, in 1869 those on sugar like- wise. Then came in 1873 the reduction of the iron duties, and finally in 1875 their entire dis- appearance was enacted from the first day of 1877. This clear abandonment of a Protectionist policy was the work of three Prussian Ministers, Martin Friedrich Rudolf Delbriick, Otto Camp- hausen, and August von der Heydt. 26 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER III. THE REACTION. It is not strictly accurate to speak of the German Customs Tariff of 1879 as a Protectionist departure.^ Recalling the proposition with which we began, Protection was the German tradition ; Free Trade, whenever it gained expression, whether as the spirit of a general policy or in temporary application to some individual branch of industry, was a plain infraction of that tradition. Moreover, it is necessary to bear in mind that what was done between the years 1S65 and 1875 was not the result of a national mandate or of a national change of mind. There were Free Trade schools, parties, and tendencies at all times, as there were in England before the epoch of repeal, » but Free Trade never became in Germany a popular cry and a party policy in the English sense, nor did its success depend at any time in any degree whatever upon the attitude of the great body of the people. We transport our English ideas of popular government and the rule of the majority into German affairs, and, led by an entirely imaginary ^ Portions of Chapters III. and V. are reproduced from the Economic Journal by permission of the Editor, Professor F. Y. Edge worth. THE REACTION. 27 and fallacious analogy, we make great mistakes. Germany — if we mean by that term the nation and not merely the Government — did not adopt Protection in 1879 ^^Y more than it adopted the bureaucracy or the police law. Apart from the will of the Sovereign and the Federal Council, Germany can neither do anything nor undo any- thing : its power is preventive and not initiative ; it may endorse or tt cgoJivc the policy given from above, but it cannot create, still less enforce, a policy of its own. If, nevertheless, we are to speak of a Protec- tionist revival, we must add that the revival began immediately Free Trade seemed to have gained a victory. It was in 1875 that the last of the protective duties were abolished, and that year saw Germany already plunged into an agitation having for its end the reintroduction of Protection in a more systematic and more drastic form. It has often been suggested by German econo- mists of the Free Trade school that the departure from the old Protectionist lines was made too quickly and at last too completely. The late Professor Albert Schaffle always contended that both sides went to extremes, and that if a moderate course had been taken not only in 1879 but earlier the result might have been a wider Customs Union, embracing Austria, on the basis of moderate Protection, instead of the succession of tariff wars which fell to later years. It is certain than when Prince Bismarck determined 28 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. to lead Germany back into the old way it soon became evident that a policy of Protection, to be genuine, must be thorough. If one were concerned to advance analogies between the national and economic circumstances which were the occasion, if not the cause, of Germany's return to Protection in 1879, after the very briefest trial of Free Trade, and the fiscal controversy which will long make the year 1903 memorable in England, the task would be easy and not altogether uninstructive. Two parallel events may be singled out. Germany, like England thirty years later, had emerged from a war which, though successfully waged, had proved a severe drain upon her economic life, had dis- organised many of her trades and industries, and had left her with much lost ground to make up. Then, again, that war had not long been con- cluded before there followed a period of com- mercial depression, which was felt all the more severely since the country's great need was rest and recuperation. That depression reached its climax in 1876 and 1877, when industry stood still and labour walked the streets idle and dis- contented, but the crisis had been ripening for several years, ever since, in fact, the unprece- dented stimulus given by the war to industry, finance, and enterprise generally had become exhausted. Up to 1870 industry had developed gradually but steadily and on healthy lines. Thus the production of pig-iron within the area of the THE REACTION. 29 Zollverein was in 1864 905,000 tons. By i86g it had grown to 1,413,000 tons, and, though it fell during the year of the French War to 1,391,000 tons, it had by the year 1873 reached 2,241,000 tons. Labour, too, had concurrently improved its status. It has been said that in the Paris insurrection of 1848 no single workman with a savings bank book was seen on the barricades. On that principle the accumulated investments of the Berlin working classes in 1871 might have indicated a tolerabl}' contented as well as a tolerably prosperous condition, for nearly three million thalers (equal to 3r45o,ooo) stood to their credit in the State savings banks, and four and a half million thalers (or £675,000) a year later. The deposits for the whole of Prussia in 1871 amounted to 172 million thalers (;£25,8oo,ooo), having increased as follows : — 1835, 5*4 million thalers; 1845, 12*5 million thalers; i855> 32*2 million thalers ; 1868, I43'5 million thalers; 1871, 172 million thalers; and 1872, 217 million thalers. In the last-named year alone new deposits were made to the extent of 83,600,000 thalers, and the number of depositors increased from 1,358,392 to 1,644,480, or 25 per cent. After the war industry took a great bound forward, similar to that which followed when the pressure of the War of Liberation, with its terrible drain upon the physical strength and the financial resources of the nation, was relieved early in the century. To the natural influences which favoured 30 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. an awakening of economic life came the influence of the French milliards, which, thanks to the wonderful elasticity of the conquered nation, were paid over long before they had been expected, and which had to be expended far too precipitately for Germany's good. Prince Bismarck once spoke of the indemnity as an acute embarrassment for the time being, and a thoughtful German writer has said : " It broke over us like a water-spout, carrying great devastation everywhere, whereas if it had fallen gradually, in the course of time, and in small quantities, it might have been bene- ficial in an extraordinary degree." The dispersal of the milliards upon railways, fortifications, and public works and buildings of various kinds gave for a time great impetus to industry, and the iron and steel trades especially expanded enormously, but the eventual reaction caused wholesale disaster. For a long time money was plentiful, and abun- dant facilities for spending it were not lacking. Speculation reached wild limits ; company pro- moting became the recognised royal road to wealth ; and the notorious Grilndirngsdra had the same sinister ending as the South Sea Bubble of our own annals. It was not long before credit became disorganised, money became hard, the Bankruptcy Court was crowded by unwilling suitors, and wreck and ruin were created whole- sale. Many fortunes were made in that mad scramble for wealth, but far more were lost ; good reputations were compromised and forfeited by THE REACTION. 31 the score, but none were created. During the three years 1871 to 1873, 843 new public com- panies were formed in Prussia, or more than four times the number which existed at the formation of the Empire. Of these companies a large number were rotten from the beginning, and soon found their way into liquidation, while in many other cases disaster was only staved off by the reduction of capital, often to the extent of 50 per cent. It was found later that of ig6 companies which reduced their capital between 1874 ^^^ 1879 no fewer than 148 originated in the " flotation era." And if capital suffered, so also did labour. For a time the working classes had shared in the general enrichment. Employment was abundant, wages increased, and with larger earnings at their disposal the labourers suddenly developed a con- suming capacity unknown before, insomuch that large food imports from abroad were needed to supplement the production at home. As wages had gone up with a bound, however, so they came down with a crash, and the absolute and perma- nent gain to labour from a period of artificially inflated prosperity was very small. It is fair to remember that the following words of the Con- servative historian Professor Heinrich von Treit- schke, written in 1874, relate to the Free Trade era, and describe the condition of the labouring class before the economic debacle of 1875 to 1877 : — " The transformation of our national economy has given to the working class a great increase of wages, 32 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. without parallel in German history. Therewith they secured, as aforetime the English working classes, the possibility of permanently improving their standard of life, and of approximating more nearly to the habits of the middle classes." That these years were nevertheless years of rapid trade expansion is proved by the compara- tive returns of imports and exports. During the years 1860-1864 Germany imported on an average 132,000 tons of pig-iron and exported 9,568 tons ; during the years 1865-1878 she imported on an average 379,214 tons (265,214 tons more) and exported 170,838 tons (161,270 tons more). The average yearly imports of half-manufactured iron increased for the period 1865-1878 I42'6 per cent, beyond those of 1860-1864, the exports 720*2 per cent. The imports of iron and steel goods increased for the period 1865- 1872 54*1 per cent, bej^ond those of 1860-1864, and the exports 52*6 per cent. ; the imports increased 1377 per cent, in the period 1873-1877 as compared with 1865- 1872, and the exports 65*2 per cent. ; and the imports increased 2*6 per cent, in 1877-1878 as compared with 1873-1877, while the exports increased 84*9 per cent. In the imports of machinery and machine parts there was an in- crease of 1987 per cent., and in the exports one of 112*9 per cent, during the period 1873-1876 as compared with 1865-1872, and during the period 1877-1878 a decrease of 5*1 per cent, in imports and an increase of 65*9 per cent, in exports, as THE REACTION. 33 compared with 1873-1876. The annual imports of cotton yarns increased 11 '8 per cent, for the period 1865-1878 as compared with 1860-1865, and the exports increased go'G per cent. The imports of cotton goods increased I23'i per cent, during 1870-1878 as compared with 1865-1869, and the exports 33*05 per cent. The imports of woollen goods decreased 247*8 per cent., and the exports increased 27*1 per cent. ; the imports of linen goods decreased 140*07 per cent., and the exports increased 36*4 per cent. ; the imports of silk and half-silk goods increased 29*4 per cent., and the exports increased 52*6 per cent. On the whole, there was a steady " passive '' balance of trade during all the 'seventies, as the following table shows : — Excess of Imports. Exports. Imports. Marks. Marks. Marks. 1872 3,468,480,000 2,494,620,000 973,860,000 1873 4.^57.333.000 2,488,998,000 1.768,335,000 1874 3.673.059.000 2,459,880,000 1,213,179,000 1875 3,576,870,000 2,561,800,000 1,015,070,000 1876 3.913.300,000 2,605,600,000 1.307.700,000 1877 3,877,080,000 2,828,560,000 1,048,520,000 1878 3,722,670,000 2,916,540,000 806,130,000 IS79 3,773,400,000 2,802,000,000 972,000,000 Agriculture w^as not slow to respond to the reaction. Prices fell, and with them land values, and where leases lapsed rents dropped as well. Up to 1874 both values and rent had steadily risen, but then came the climax, and after it the : decline. Apart altogether from the depression in P.G. D 34 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. domestic industr}' and trade, the corn growers had to contend with severe competition from abroad, favoured by improved ocean transport, by extended railway facihties, and still more by the develop- ment which agriculture was undergoing in Austria, Russia, and the United States. Hence Germany became less an exporting and more an importing countr}'. During the period 1868 to 1872 the average imports of wheat were 415,650 tons and the exports 562,450 tons, an excess of exports of 146,800 tons ; but from 1873 to 1877 the average imports were 586,700 tons and the exports 497,750 tons, an excess of imports of 88,050 tons. Simi- larly the yearly imports of rye during the years 1868-1872 averaged 465,800 tons and the exports 164,500 tons, an excess of imports of 301,300 tons, while in the later period the imports averaged 955,050 tons and the exports 156,350, an excess of imports of 798,700 tons. The imports from Russia, by land or water, in 1875 were 343,466 tons of rye, 26,500 tons of barley, and 118,433 tons of oats, a total of 488,399 tons ; in 1876 they were 566,057 tons of rye, 29,715 tons of barley, and 159,802 tons of oats, a total of 755,574 tons ; and in 1877 they were 663,310 tons of rye, 96,038 tons of barley, and 181,022 tons of oats, a total of 940,070 tons. This larger import of grain was not only due to the increased consumption but to the less area of land under the plough. While in the beginning of the 'sixties 56 per cent, of the area of Prussia was under corn, the proportion fell by THE REACTION. 35 1878 to 5072 per cent. The area under rye was greater, but that under wheat, barley, and oats had dedined. In later years a counter movement set in. So, too, in the still more agricultural State of Bavaria the area under rye decreased between 1866 and 1878 from 588,479 to 579,416 hectares, the area under barley from 338,863 to 320,534 hectares, and that under oats from 451,752 to 439,551 hectares. The area under wheat in- creased from 290,255 to 298,779 hectares, but the total result was a decrease from 1,856,577 to 1,765,746 hectares, a leakage of 90,831 hectares, or over 226,000 acres, in fifteen years. Finally, it is to be noted that simultaneously the products of German manufacture had fallen into a certain disrepute all over the world. In the Philadelphia Exhibition of 1876, German exhibits took great prominence, and deep was the mortification when Professor Reuleux, who had been commissioned by the National Zeitung to report upon them, summarised his impressions in the memorable phrase, " cheap and bad " {billig und schlecht). There was nothing new, however, in the accusation, save its mordant utterance and the untoward circumstances which evoked it. The Consular reports of the period all witness to the same thing, and some months before warning came from Philadelphia, the Imperial Gazette (March loth, 1876) had seriously reviewed the complaints which had long been accumulating D 2 36 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. from foreign, and especially trans-oceanic, coun- tries of inferior goods, declining sales, and lost markets. A little later the Preiissisches Handels- archiv proclaimed the same disconcerting fact in periods which spared neither the pride nor the feelings of those concerned, German trade, it said, had forfeited its reputation, not only for efficiency, but for honesty. The textile stuffs sent abroad were made contrary to the samples ordered ; they were exported deficient in measure and weight ; qualities were mixed ; and in general they were coarse, clumsy, and tasteless. And, coming to comparisons, it asserted: " The German no longer possesses the capacity of the English manufacturer, who is able to make even cheap goods so efficiently, and to turn them out so attractively, that large repeat orders are regularly given, whereas the German executes commissions of the same kind so faultily that he is seldom able to secure a second order." Moreover, *' the Englishman is always ready to consider a merchant's legitimate complaints, while the German will never make compensation for loss suffered." In reply to these and similar com- plaints, the manufacturer pointed to the un- protected frontiers. " How can we compete abroad," he asked, ** with an older, richer, and better equipped rival like England, so long as even our home market is not preserved to us, and we are compelled to sell to the foreigner, by hook or by crook, in order to dispose of our THE REACTION. 37 production at all?"^ Faults which were entirely- due to remediable inefficiency were thus attri- buted to the prevalent fiscal system, and were made a further count in the growing indictment against it. Reading the literature of the time, one notices how great was the influence of the "protection of young industries" argument in converting even theoretical Free Traders to the advocacy of temporary measures of Protection, in view of the peculiar condition of economic life. They regarded such measures as useful educa- tionally, and their purpose once achieved, they assumed that they would promptly be discarded as superfluous and even dangerous. That there was then and later ample room for improvement was shown by a capable German critic of the Berlin Industrial Exhibition of 1879: — " While wc are able to detect with joyous satis- faction the progress and tlie high degree of efficiency which some of our products have attained, on the other hand other departments of the exhibition remind us clearly of tlie great work which yet lies before us before we can come abreast of our neighbours." But such being the economic condition of Germany in the early seventies, and remember- ing that these years had marked the first clear ' An argument which Prince Bismarclc frequent!}' em- ployed, as, for example, in a speech made in the Reichstag on June 14th, 1882 : — " England had the highest protective duties until she had been so strengthened under the pro- tection that she came forward as a herculean fighter and challenged everybody with, 'Enter the hsts with me.' She is the strongest pugilist in the arena of competition, and is ever ready to assert the right of the strongest in trade." 38 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. departure from Protection, what was more likely than that, reasoning a priori, so far as reasoning can be said to enter into the judgment of persons who believe themselves to be suffering from injustice, the industries and interests which had fallen on evil days should have united in casting the blame on the new-fangled policy of Free Trade ? And Free Trade being responsible for their misfortune, where else could a remedy be found save in a return to the discarded Protective system ? Add to this that the " National" cry was then in the air, as with us the cry of " Imperialism " to-day. Germany had just become a nation, so let her institutions be made truly national as well ; let her become independent, economically as well as politically, a self- controlled, self-supporting Empire ! To that were evidently necessary an all-sufficient industry and an all-sufficient granary, and these, argued the Nationalists, could only be supplied if industry and agriculture were effectively protected against foreign competition. Nor can it be denied that if Protection could be judged capable of rescuing the economy of the country from its apparent condition of decadence, there were reasons specious enough to justify its advocates in demanding that the attempt should be made. In passing, it is interesting to remember that it was the condition of the iron and textile trades which determined the return to Protection from the industrial standpoint, and these were the industries which were in a special measure THE REACTION. 39 influenced by the political events of 1870 and 187 1. The iron and steel and allied industries, as we have seen, shared liberally in the distribution of the French milliards, but directly the abnormal expenditure on State and public works ceased stagnation began, and many industrialists found themselves in possession of works and plants which had been built or extended on an exces- sive scale in order to meet what had proved to be a temporary and transient spell of prosperity. In 1873 over-production had reached such a limit in the iron trade that it is estimated by Lotz that the smelting and rolling works of Germany were then producing iron enough to cover the demand of the entire world. Prices sank enormously. Having reached their highest point in 1873, they sank more than 50 per cent, the following year, and by 1878 they were barely 30 per cent, what they had been five years before. The protection against foreign competition which the iron trade had enjoyed ceased, as we have seen, with the 3^ear 1876, and it is noticeable that the Emperor, and probably his Chancellor as well, doubted from the first the wisdom of Dr. Delbriick's action, though they appear to have raised no pro- test. Writing to Prince Bismarck from Gastein on July 22nd, 1876, the Emperor William said : — " As there was so little time at Wurzburg, I was not able again to bring up a subject in connexion with our internal affairs which, in spite of reports by Uelbriick and Camphausen before you came to 40 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. Berlin in the autumn, has continually occupied ray attention, and especially during my recent Rhine journey — I mean the stagnation in our iron trade. It was shown to me in those reports that our export of iron still exceeds the imports. I inquired how it happened that one ironworks after another is closing its doors and dismissing its workmen (who can find no employment elsewhere), and that those which con- tinue working do so at a loss, and must also soon blow out their fires. I was told in reply, ' Yes, that is the state of affairs ; but in such general calamitous times individuals must be ruined, and we are more fortunate than other countries ' (Belgium). Is that a politically wise conception of the case ? Matters have, unfortunately, been in this state for several years. And from January ist, 1877, iron is to be imported into Germany free of all duty, whereas France is introducing a premium on her export of iron to Germany. The consequence of such conditions as these can only be that what still remains of our iron trade must be ruined. I by no means desire that the much-praised system of Free Trade shall be given up, but I must request that before the Reichstag reassembles the question be again ventilated ' whether the Bills allowing foreign iron to be admitted into Germany duty-free must not be temporarily postponed for a year ? ' If you agree with me, I await your report as to what arrangements you will make." On the other hand the textile trade had been hard hit by the incorporation in the Empire of the large and progressive weaving and spinning indus- tries of Alsace. Hitherto these industries had sold to France almost exclusively ; but now their production was largely thrown upon the German market, so that the less efficient and less wealthy manufacturers of Saxony found themselves face to face with a new and severe competition. BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 41 CHAPTER IV. PRINCE BISMARCK'S THEORIES OF TAXATION. It would be absurd to attempt to bind a states- man to every opinion he may happen to have held from the first days of his public life. Changed conditions require changed policies, and the politi- cal steersman who refuses to accommodate his craft to wind and tide may indeed reach a haven, but it will seldom be the haven which he desired. None the less instructive is it, however, to know that Prince Bismarck's earliest Parliamentary utterances show him to have been a thorough- going Free Trader in practice, however theory may have fared. Speaking in the Prussian Lower House on October 19th, 1849, thirty years before he diverted the policy of the Empire into Pro- tectionist lines, he said : " The Deputy for Crefeld regards the protective duty as a protection of the manufactories against foreign countries, while I, on the other hand, regard it as a protection against the liberty of the native population to buy where it may appear cheapest and most convenient, in other words, the protection of the home country against the home country. Protective duties and compulsory guilds impose a sacrifice upon a part of the population for the benefit of the other part, especially the obligation to buy goods at a 42 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. higher price than would otherwise be the case, in order that this other part of the population may be ensured bread and be protected. But protective duties have also the disadvantage that in the main they only enrich a few factory proprietors. This is their sole result, for I have never seen that factory operatives have put away large savings or become rich. On the contrary, I have known rural labourers, on manors of the Eastern Provinces thoroughly familiar to me, who have been able, after working during their best years, to buy settlements or small peasant holdings. I know of no poor on the manors of the Eastern Provinces, but 1 wish I could say the same of the Western factory districts." Doubtless it was the ardent agriculturist who spoke here, the advocate of the country as against the town, of the plough as against the loom. Did he not once say that if he had his way the large towns should be swept from the face of the earth ? And yet if it be conceded that young Herr von Bismarck had not reasoned himself into this atti- tude by the study of economic text-books, he had certainly arrived at the very definite conclusion that protective laws are partial laws, which promote the material interest of the few at the expense of the resources and the convenience of the many. Not only so, but it is an arguable contention that Prince Bismarck never became genuinely convinced of the economic wisdom of Protection. To the last he protested that he was " never passionately attached " to protective duties, and his favourite arguments were always the political and financial arguments — expediency on the one hand and revenue on the other — while BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 43 on the question of principle he was always ready to make concessions to his opponents which really involved the very substance of their objections. Coming to a later period, when he had already been in office some years, we find him objecting to all duties which were not levied for purely fiscal purposes, and especially those duties which inflicted a disproportionate amount of hardship upon the poor. " I am always seized with a certain feeling of regret," he said in the Customs Parliament on June 21st, 1869, " that we do not express ourselves with full and real candour when I hear pathetic laments about the ' poor man ' who sees his petroleum, his light, his intelligence, and his tobacco taxed, coming from the very lips that say ' Yes ' to the taxation of flour, bread, even fuel, meat, and salt at the expense of the same ' poor man ' without any qualms of conscience whatever. I do not deny that a harsh expression hovers on m}- lips when I hear that kind of lament. I am not able to follow such reasoning, and I doubt whether the common people, for whom you are so solicitous, can follow it either." And again on the same occasion : — " I think that our customs legislation should be developed in the direction of the ideal of pure financial duties, not, perhaps, attaining this ideal, but striving to approach it. I call it an ideal because it will perhaps prove to be unattainable. It is the common task of yourselves and the Federal Council to prevent this approach from taking place too precipitously, so as to expose to injury the native industries which have hitherto been fostered and protected by legislation. I own that in aiming in 44 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. this direction we should conserve rightful interests. If, however, we would revert to financial duties we must seek out the proper objects for taxation, and among these I unreservedl}' give to petroleum the ^ first place. It is one of those articles of consumption which are not so absolutely indispensable as bread, salt, and meat — which, however, we likewise tax — and which have already, or promise to have, so extensive a consumption that a moderate duty affords at once the prospect of considerable revenue." But, in truth, Bismarck never made any conceal- ment of the fact that upon economic as upon political questions he was an opportunist of the first water, and that his course was invariably dictated by practical considerations alone, so that if national expediency and interest, as he conceived them, required that principle and theory should be abandoned, abandoned they must be. Speak- ing on February 21st, 1879, during a debate on the Austrian treaty of commerce, he said : — " If I were to contradict myself I should for appear- ance sake very much lament it, but if I saw that it was necessary in the national interest to retrace a way which I acknowledged to be fallacious I should not hesitate for a moment to confess my error openly and either to make room for someone who would manage matters better than I, or, if required, to do better myself." One of his biographers, Dr. Poschinger, writing of him during his lifetime, said truly : — " Bismarck the economist has passed through a certain course of development, always guided by circumstances, which seemed to require now this, now that, line of action. One would not be justified in BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 45 tracing his economic views to any certain system, v Were one to say that Prince Bismarck is a Protec- tionist, one would make a great mistake. He will be a Free Trader as soon as his neighbours do away with their customs, perhaps even in a moment when he hopes to influence their commercial policy by / Germany's example. He favours taxation where the financial interests of the country require it, and protective duties where he thinks a country without them is going to economic ruin. Thus he would advocate a tobacco monopoly or a tobacco duty, according as the one or the other proposal had hopes of fulfilment, and according as want of money was greater or smaller. He is opposed to a customs union with Austria, and only sympathises with a similar project when it seems to him to be politically and economicallv useful. The prosperity of his fatherland is his only guiding star. Here we come to a trait of his character which cannot be passed! over. One cannot separate the economist Bismarck 1 from the politician, but the former must be subordinate I to the latter." This, after all, is but a paraphrase of his own reiterated words. " Since I became Minister," he told the Reichstag in July, 1879, "I have never belonged to a faction, and I would not. I have been hated by all in turn and loved by several. That has gone on a tour de role.'' But he, for his part, hated and loved in turn, using or discarding party after party just as they showed themselves willing to assist him in carrying out his tasks. He had to pay their price, which was sometimes usurious, but having bought his support he deemed it fair to refuse to continue the contract when its time had expired. 46 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. " I have never had but one compass, one pole star, after which I have steered, salus piiblica," he said in the Reichstag on February 24th, 1881, " I have often, perhaps, acted rashly and indiscreetly ; but when I have had time to reflect I have always subordinated myself to the question ; what is useful, expedient, and right for my fatherland — for my dynasty, so long as I belonged to Prussia only, and nowadays for the : German nation? Never in my life have I been a doctrinaire : all systems by which parties are divided and bound together are of secondary importance for me ; the first place I give to the nation, its position abroad, its independence, the organisation necessary in order that we as a nation may breathe freely in the world." Such being the principles of his public action, it is no surprise to find that the economic policy which he pursued during the first decade and a half of his Ministerial life was in general sympa- thetic to Free Trade, for the interests of the country at that time seemed to require that it , should be so. The commercial treaty which he .( concluded with France in 1862 was distinctly Free Trade in principle, yet, as we have seen, the motives which prompted him to this step were political rather than economic. In 1873 he agreed to the abolition of the remaining iron duties, and they did in fact disappear from January ist, 1877. In 1875 he advocated the restriction of the tariff to ten or a dozen articles, with a view to the retention of merely fiscal duties. Holding theory so lightly, and insisting that practical considera- tions, as he recognised and interpreted them, must be the sole determinative of his action, it was not BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 47 difficult for Prince Bismarck to detach himself from his earlier traditions and to come forward as a Protectionist. On April 28th, 1877, the Govern- ment were asked by interpellation to institute an investigation into the state of industry and agri- culture, so far as related to the conditions of pro- duction and sale, but the invitation was not sym- pathetically received at the time. And yet Prince Bismarck has named the year 1877 as that of his formal, or more truly official, conversion. Speaking in the Reichstagon November 2gth, i88i,hesaid: — " During the first fifteen years of my Ministerial life I was absorbed by foreign politics, and I did not feel called on to trouble myself much with the internal politics of the Empire, nor indeed had I the necessary time. I took it for granted that our domestic concerns were in good hands. Afterwards, when I lost the help that I thought reliable, I was compelled to look into matters myself and I found that while I had up to then sworn in verba mogistri, the actual results did not support the theories upon which our legislation was based. I had the impression that under the Free Trade system introduced in 1865 we fell into a condition of decline, which was indeed staved off for a time by the new blood which came with the five milliards, and that it was necessary to find a remedy." Asked by an opponent on February 21st, 1879, whether in 1862, when concluding the commercial treaty with France, he shared the "economic [Protectionist] tendencies" of his later years, he replied with characteristic candour : — "I should be proud if, as is alleged, I had had ' economic tendencies ' of the kind, but I must confess 48 PROTECTION IN GERMANY to my shame that I had not. . . . Had I really been convinced that the policy of the President of the Chancellery [of the North German Confederation] was disastrous for our economic life, I should have been justified in counteracting it. It might have led to the President's earlier withdrawal, but my formal right was beyond doubt. But when for a task like that of the consolidation of the German Empire in its first beginnings, or of the North German Con- federation, as a prelude to the German Empire, I secured the co-operation of a statesman of the importance in his own domain of Deputy Delbriick, it is clear that I could not pretend to require that President Delbriick should conduct economic policy, in which he was the first authority in all Germany, according to my direc- tions ; but it was naturally understood cum gvano salis that (as was in reality the case) I should with con- fidence leave matters with him, and I am far from saying that I regret this confidence. ... I did not mix in economic questions, but tried to secure the most prominent men and statesmen who were willing to help me in carrying out the work which I had undertaken. It is beyond doubt that I did not hold the economic views of the then President, and when I did not follow them I do not know how matters were arranged, though I fancy I must in most cases have given in, because politically I was glad to sacri- fice my own opinions in order to retain so valuable co-operation for the cause I had in hand." And again he said in the Prussian House of Deputies on February 4th, 1881 : — " Before I went into customs questions myself I had no special opinions of my own, but fell in with those of my colleague Delbriick, whom I regarded as the right man in the right place. At that time I had no time to form any definite conception of commercial policy. I deny that my earlier views were different from those of to-day, for in truth I had none at all ; BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 49 I was the diligent disciple of Herr Delbriick, and when I have avowed any views at all they were his views. When he left me I was compelled to form my own; they are perhaps in many respects different from his, but I did not formerly hold antagonistic views which I have since changed." It was thus natural that when at last Prince < Bismarck resorted to Protection it was under the spur of financial necessity rather than of economic conviction. No one who has waded through the • Parliamentary proceedings of that time can resist the conclusion that the reform of Imperial taxa-; tion was the Chancellor's underlying motive, and' that this reform of taxation was primarily under- . . taken with the object of providing the Empire ' - with a sufficient independent revenue, so that it need no longer rely on the States and their Legislatures. In the forefront of domestic needs he had for years placed fiscal reform. "The entire reform of taxation, inclusive of the customs duties — who does not wish it ? " he said in the Reichstag on November 22nd, 1875. " But it is a Herculean work which one must have touched experimentally as a comparative layman in these matters, such as I am, in order to really com- prehend its difficulties." Moreover, so long as the pressure of foreign questions continued, it had been impossible to essay this great task, inherited from the very establishment of the Empire. The Imperial Constitution adopted in 1871 had ■ provided that in so far as the expenditure of the Empire was not covered by revenues set apart for P.G. E 50 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. its special use the deficienc)' should be made up by contributions from the Federal States accord- ing to population. These were known as matri- cular contributions, and their aggregate amount was fixed each year in the Imperial budget. Prince Bismarck always chafed under this system of State maintenance, which he regarded as undignified and as partaking of the character of a species of poor relief, while at the same time holding that the disproportionate incidence of the matricular contributions created a rightful feeling of injustice and inequality on the part of those populations which bore too large a share. It was undignified, because it made the Empire and those responsible for the transaction of its affairs dependent upon the good-will of the various States, which meant in the last resort the humour of their Legislatures and the caprice of the electors. It was unjust, because it was based on taxation according to population, irrespective of the considerations of wealth and ability to pay. To this aspect of the question he referred on November 22nd, 1875, in the speech already named : — " Speaking entirely from the standpoint of the Empire, I seek as great a reduction as possible, if not the complete abolition, of the matricular contribu- tions. It is scarcely disputed that the form of the matricular contributions is one that does not fall upon the contributary States in proportion to their capacity. 1 might say that it is a crude form, which may serve as a makeshift so long as we are not able BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 51 to provide the Empire, in its early youth, with revenues of its own. If, however, it is acknowledged that it is a tax which is not just in its incidence, it cannot be regarded as a means of consolidating the Empire." He had always held it to be unreasonable that, to cite his favourite illustration, 30,000 inhabitants of agricultural Thuringia or Waldeck should pay as much as the same number of citizens of wealthy mercantile towns like Hamburg and Bremen. Earlier than this — on May ist, 1872 — he had told the Reichstag, when speaking of the salt tax: — "The position of the Imperial Chancellor is pri- marily determined by the consideration whether the political condition of the Empire would be made better or worse by the abolition of an Imperial tax, and whether the responsibility to the Empire which rests upon him is so heavy as to compel him to resist its abolition on political grounds. I regard the Empire's independent revenues as so important that I do not believe a Chancellor conscious of his respon- sibility, and actuated by a proper concern for the stability and development of the Empire, could con- sent to the diminution of these revenues unless an adequate substitute were provided. Dependence upon other taxes is problematic, and dependence upon matricular contributions I cannot accept at all. The great cement of a strong common financial system is lacking to the Empire so long as it is founded only on matricular contributions. That these contribu- tions fall unequally is a question of justice, but to diminish them is in my opinion the task of a well- considered Imperial policy." Above all there was the political aspect of the question. Prince Bismarck lived in constant E 2 52 PROTFXTION IN GERMANY. '' dread of the "centrifugal elements" which did not share his own attachment to the Empire or his own conviction of its permanency. The spirit of particularism was not dead — is not dead to- day — and he desired to make the Empire as independent as possible by placing it in possession of ample and elastic resources. He did not want the citizens of the new Confederation to be per- petually asking themselves, as they reckoned out the incidence of the matricular contributions, "What does the new Empire cost me, and is it worth the price?" The financial aspect of the Empire he therefore wished once for all to force into the background. These were not appre- hensions which so shrewd a statesman as he could safely avow, for to have done so would have encouraged the forces which were ranged against him, and might at the same time have defeated his entire scheme ; and one of the secrets of successful statesmanship is to get your own way while allowing your opponents to believe that they are getting theirs. " The Imperial contribution," he told the Reichstag on one occasion, " presupposes that the condition of matricular contributions will be a transitional one, lasting only until Imperial taxes shall have been introduced. . . . The consolidation of the Empire will be promoted when the matricular contributions are replaced by Imperial taxes ; it would not lose if these taxes were so prohibitive that the individual States received from the Empire instead of their having to give in a way that is not always computable and is for them inconvenient." BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 53 Besides, as he reminded the same pugnacious body at another time, the Empire " had not yet grown strong enough to be made the arena for trials of strength " between State and State. Further, Prince Bismarck was powerfully influenced by his conviction, in which he never wavered, of the inexpediency of direct taxation, and the political wisdom as well as the personal convenience of the policy of raising revenue by indirect means — on the one hand by financial customs duties and on the other by excise dues on articles of internal production and consump- tion. A volume would be taken up by the speeches which he made in the Reichstag alone upon this, one of his favourite themes. For years the basis of taxation in Prussia had been the land, income, class, building, and trade taxes, all of which had existed since 1861 and several for a much longer time. For not one of these taxes had Bismarck a good word to say, and if he never made any serious attempt to abolish them it was because he saw no hope of obtaining a satisfactory equivalent elsewhere. His idea, however, w-as indirect taxation as far as possible, and direct taxes on income and capital only to the extent that they fell upon the very rich, and even then only by way of public recognition of their splendid material isolation from the rest of their fellow- men. His own term for imposts of this kind, so emphatically partial and class in character, was "honorary taxes" {Ehrensteuei'). 54 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. As early as May 21st, 1869, we find him telling the Prussian Diet that it was his desire so to arrange taxation that it might be levied with the least possible pressure upon those liable, hence to rely as little as possible upon direct taxes. " Direct taxes," he said, " always press on the tax- payers with a certain angular brutality. I do not count amongst these taxes the tax on light (petro- leum), nor yet those on the necessaries of life, like bread and salt, and if I cared to talk about the cruelty of embittering ' the poor man's ' pipe of tobacco or invigorating drink, and yet were conscious at the same time that I still required from him the poll-tax and the bread-tax, I should be honest enough to ask myself ' What do you really mean by such hypocrisy ? ' So long as we tax bread, so long as we continue to demand the bread-penny from every member of the labourer's family, yet tax but slightly or not at all those luxuries which, indeed, I would concede to every man, even the poorest, yet which, when he has no money, he must for a time at least dispense with, so long do I hold the complaint about the flour tax, the meat tax, and the bread tax to be absolutely justified." 1 Hence, too, in a speech made in the Reichstag on November 22nd, 1875, he said : — " I declare myself as essentially favourable to the raising of all possible revenue by indirect taxes, and I hold direct taxes to be an onerous and awkward makeshift. . . . Indirect taxes, whatever may be said against them theoretically, are in fact less felt. It is difficult for the individual to calculate how much he pays, and how much falls upon Itis neighbours, but he knows how much income tax he pays. . . . ' The Mahlsteuey, a tax on ground corn, and the Schlacht- stener, a tax on live stock killed for food, were a1)olishcd January ist, 1875. BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 55 With direct taxes a man is not asked : Can you on a pinch do without }-our beer ; can you smoke less ; can you use less light (petroleum) of an evening ? No, he must pay the direct tax whether he has money or not, whether in debt or not ; and what is worse, distraint follows, and nothing has a greater effect on a man's disposition than execution on account of a few pence which cannot at the moment be extorted from the one who owes them." Holding thus the view that direct taxation and discontent went hand in hand, it is hardly a wonder that he later went a step further and came to identify the advocacy of such taxation with hostility to authority and to attribute to it mis- chievous political intent. " Those who want to see the electors dissatisfied \ with the Government will hold fast to the direct taxes ; 1 those who seek to promote content in the population 1 will be more for indirect. That is the result of practice \ and experience, and I need not develop the psychologi- cal reason for it. Whoever offers opposition wants to see discontent amongst the people, and will devise means to find it and to excite it, by representing the Government as incapable, malevolent, and perhaps only as clumsy." In a speech made on February 22nd, 1878, in which he contended that " at this moment every hundred million marks levied in England and France are raised with less pressure on the popula- tion than with us," he justified direct taxes on other grounds — whether conclusively or not is a question apart : — " Indirect taxes are preferable to direct not merely because of the advantages in the mode of raising them, the superfluity of executions and distraints, and 56 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the fact that the taxpayer fixes both the time and measure of his taxation ; tlieir great superiority is to be sought in their counterbalancing effect, by virtue of which the indirect pressure of taxes is distributed, in a manner varying according to local circumstances and the conjunctures of trade, among all those per- sons who are affected, from the production or import of the object taxed to its consumption. While direct taxes, for the most part, fall entirely and immovably upon those liable, who cannot transfer them to others, and are often threatened v-'ith distraint, an indirect tax is primarily taken from the one liable, but he is able, so far as home products are concerned, to transfer the tax he has paid to the buyers of his goods, while as for taxed articles imported from abroad the pro- ducing countr}" wholly or partially bears the tax. Since the indirect tax is, as a rule, incorporated with the other competing factors which go to the forma- tion of price, as one of the less important elements of a now indivisible whole, its burdensome effect upon the individual, not apparently, but to a great measure actually, disappears. Thus all the advantages ad- vanced on behalf of direct taxes can at the most claim a theoretical value. In theory the tendency to affect the individual in proportion to his capacity, which lies at the basis of these taxes, may be esti- mated too high ; the practical form of such taxes very seldom fits in with this theory. The financial capacity of the individual taxpayer is not always expressed in his income, apart from the general impossibility of calculating that income even approxi- mately. Family position, health, and local and other circumstances, which direct taxation disregards and must disregard, create the greatest diversity in actual financial position even among persons of equal income." It is noteworthy also that Prince Bismarck was a decided advocate of the exemption of small incomes from taxation of all kinds. BISMARCK'S THEORIES. 57 " I hold in general," he said on February 4th, i88r, "the principle that the man who has nothing but liis two hands — untrained hands, that is, wliich have learned no industry — wherewith to earn his liveli- hood, should be entirely exempted from taxation — not only from State taxation, but from communal imposts as well — and that taxation should only begin when another capital exists. This capital may take the form of physical or mental skill, but it should in my opinion be above the level of the simple artisan, who has not been able to learn anything, not because of his own fault, but from lack of means for his education. ... He whose means are such that he has nothing in the world to depend upon but uncer- tain employment — as in Berlin here, clearing away snow in winter and digging in summer — should, in my opinion, be required by the State to do nothing but help in time of war to defend against the stranger the roof which protects him. He should not be called upon to pay money." 58 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER V. THE TARIFF OF 1879. Nothing can be clearer or more indisputable than that up to 1878 Prince Bismarck and the Federal Government entertained no idea whatever of industrial and agricultural Protection. The revision of the tariff was already determined on, but the revision was to be undertaken solely in the interest of revenue ; the duties to be imposed or increased, as might happen, were to be regarded as fiscal, not protective duties. The Govern- ment's position was sketched by the semi-official Provinzial-Corrcspondenz as follows : — " The Government seek no reaction in the domain either of politics or of taxation and economics, but merely a rational development. Instead of anarchy and tlie subversion of monarchical, constitutional and social institutions, as well as the institution of pro- perty, they desire the energetic interference of the State for the protection of our culture and our civili- sation and the progress of our industrial activity. While in regard to taxation 'they aim at a rational reform, which will promote the interests of the Empire as well as of the individual States, and alleviate the burdens which fall upon the nation, in regard to mercantile questions they seek to protect national interests on the lines of the development which has taken place since 1818 and the found- ing of tho Customs Union, and that without any THE TARIFF OF 1879. 59 prepossession for the doctrines of those politico-econo- mical parties which, out of regard for a supposed consistency of opinion, have overlooked the practical interests of the nation." In August the Finance Ministers of the various States met in conference at Heidelberg, and here likewise the same views were represented, the same intention adhered to. Their report merely recommended the increase of the Imperial revenue by means of a tobacco duty and of duties on certain suitable fiscal articles. It was at this point that the question was taken out of Bismarck's hands to be developed and settled in a way w'hich he had hitherto never seriously anticipated. For the party of reaction in the Reichstag had meantime been active. They recognised that the moment was propitious for a return to the policy discarded under the influence of Minister Delbruck, and thanks to the promptitude, urgency, and vigour of their interposition they were able to create the impetus which sent the Chancellor, while still wavering with open mind, clear across the border line which divided fiscal from protective policy. Already he had reconstituted his Ministry, which was a task of no great difficulty. Alluding once to the inci- dent in a conversation with myself, Prince Bismarck said that his Free Trade colleagues of that day " left him." Minister Delbruck, it is true, had already gone voluntarily, for he took his leave in June of 1876, and he was now a member 6o PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of the Reichstag. The only serious obstacle to the new policy was Camphausen, Vice-President of the Prussian Ministry of State, who had suc- ceeded Von der Heydt as Minister of Finance in i86g. His retirement, voluntary or not, took place in March, 1878. Now the Chancellor took the helm in his own hand, and more than the helm, for he made himself responsible henceforth for Germany's policy in every detail, both at home and abroad. Like the survivor of the famine- stricken craft of the ballad, he was captain, mate, boatswain, cook and all. For many years to come Bismarck was literally the State. The political portents of the time were favour- able to reaction. The re-election of the Reichstag which followed the two attempts of May nth and June 2nd, 1878, upon the life of the Emperor Wil- liam I. placed the Liberal fractions in a minority. The two Conservative groups numbered 78 in the House of 1877, 116 in that of 1878, and while the National Liberals fell from 128 to 99, the Radicals and the Socialists fell from 51 to 36. The Ultra- montane Centrum, the most unvarying of all parties, added one to its- earlier 93. Liberalism was in bad case. The Conservatives and Clericals alone would have outnumbered the popular parties and the mildly progressive National Liberals combined by 76 votes (210 to 135), even had a grouping so favourable to Liberal policy been possible. It soon appeared, however, that Free Trade would have to contend against odds far more THE TARIFF OF 1879. 61 desperate, which made the issue of the fiscal en- counter from the very beginning a foregone conclu- sion. In the course of the new session 204 Conserva- tive, Clerical, National Liberal, and other deputies, forming a majority of the House, consorted in the ''Free Economic Union of the Reichstag," with a view to deciding upon joint action on the impend- ing fiscal reforms, and on October 17th they published a formal declaration of Protectionist faith and policy. This declaration was believed to have previously received the sanction, and it was certainly issued with the knowledge of the Imperial Chancellor, whose hand it unques- tionably strengthened. It stated : — " Throughout the German Empire a clear and definite decision regarding the basis of German com- mercial relationships is awaited from the Federal Governments with suspense. It was therefore both desirable and essential that tlie Reichstag now assembled should weigh the questions connected with the Imperial Government's attitude towards com- mercial policy. The undersigned members of the Reichstag express regret that such a course was not possible inasmuch as the only purpose of the convo- cation of the Reichstag was the consideration of the Socialist Bill, and the inquiries into the economic position and the vital conditions of several of the principal industries of Germany are not yet com- pleted. In order, however, to remove the erroneous impression that the Legislature lacks the necessary interest in the nation's rightful claims in the domain of commercial policy, and a resolute will to give effect to these claims, we feel bound to declare that we have been solely prevented by the reason stated from taking the initiative as expected by the country, 62 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. and that, in view of the mercantile policy adopted by mobt of the countries adjacent to Germany, of the injury caused to the national welfare by the de- ficiencies of the German customs tariff, and of the con- tinuance of the crisis in German industry and agri- culture, we regard as necessary a reform of the tariff based on careful investigation and deliberation, and we are therefore resolved to advocate the same in the next ordinary session of the Reichstag. Although viewing the question from various commercial-political stand- points, the undersigned are agreed in the fundamental idea that the difficult questions comprehended in German mercantile policy are not altogether to be settled by the watchwords of ' Free Trade ' and ' Protective Duties,' but that what must be done is to reconcile real and supposed conflicts of inte- rests by the display of knowledge, discretion and patriotism." While the country was pondering the signifi- cance of this unexpected move, and was wondering what would happen next, Prince Bismarck was in bus3^ correspondence with Baron von Varnbiiler, a prominent member of the Economic Union and formerly a Wiirtemberg Minister, who had sought the formal avowal of his views and intentions. Writing on October 25th, Bismarck informed his correspondent that it was '' certainly m}^ intention to proceed to a thorough revision of our customs tariff and in the first place to lay proposals before the Federal Governments for prior examination. The preparations to this end have already begun. I shall not be prepared to consider the conclusion of new commercial treaties with conventional tariffs until the revision of our tariff is completed." Accordingly the Chancellor on November 12th THE TARIFF OF 1879. 63 brought the question before the Federal Council, which at his proposal appointed a committee of fifteen members to revise the tariff and to call in the aid of such experts as they might desire to con- sult in so doing. In justifying this course Prince Bismarck now frankly avowed his acceptance of the Protectionist position, though his first public utterance on the subject was contained in a letter of December 15th, which he addressed from Friedrichsruh through the Federal Council to the Revision Committee before it began its work. " For myself the interests of financial reform take the first place," he still took care to say, " the diminution of the weight of direct taxation by the increase of the revenue of the Empire which is based on indirect taxes. How far Germany lags behind other States in the financial development of its customs system is shown by the accompanying com- parison, and this comparison would show Germany in a still more unfavourable light if to the revenues from customs and duties credited to Austria, Hungary, France, and Italy were added the sums which these States levy in the form of a tobacco monopoly, instead of a duty on foreign tobacco, and those which are raised for the benefit of the communes as octroi. It is no accident that other great States, and especially those of a very advanced political and economic development, seek by preference to cover their expenditure by the proceeds of duties and indirect taxes. ... In the greater part of Germany the direct taxes, including the communal imposts, have reached a height which is oppressive and appears to be economically unjustifiable. The people who suffer most from them at present are those members of the middle class whose income ranges up to 6,000 marks (^300). . , Should the taxation reform which I regard 64 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. as necessary offer ameliorations tlial reat li to this limit, it must begin with the revision of the customs tariff on as broad a basis as possible. The more pro- ductive the customs system is made financially, the greater can and must be the relief in direct taxes, for it is self-evident that the increase of the indirect revenues of the Empire cannot imply an increase of the aggregate burden of taxation. " Not in the increase of the burdens which are necessary for the purposes of the Empire and the States, but in the transformation of a larger part of these unavoidable burdens into the less oppressive form of indirect taxes, consists the financial reform which it is the purpose of the revision of the customs tariff to effect. In order to obtain a basis for such revision consonant with this standpoint it is in my opinion desirable not merely to impose higher duties upon those articles which are specially suitable, but to go back to the principle of the taxation of all imported articles which is laid down in the Prussian customs legislation of the year 1818 and later found expression in the universal import duty of the tariff of the ZoUverein until the year 1865. From this general liability to duty those raw materials indis- pensable to industry would be excluded which are either not produced at all in Germany, like cotton, or are not produced in sufficient quantity or quality. All articles not specially excluded should be subject to an import duty graded, according to the value of the goods, in various percentages according as they are necessary for home production." Questions of economic theory had no value for a statesman who carried his disregard for theory of every kind to the point of pedantry ; a statesman whose prejudice against everything that was doctrinaire made him doctrinaire himself. " I leave undecided," proceeded the letter, " the question whether complete mutual freedom of THE TARIFF OF 1879. 65 international commerce, such as is contemplated by the theory of free trade, would not serve the interests of Germany. But as long as most of the countries with which our trade is carried on surround themselves with customs barriers, which there is still a growing tendency to multiply, it does not seem to me justifi- able, or to the economic interests of the nation, that we should allow ourselves to be restricted in the satis- faction of our financial wants by the apprehension that German products will thereby be but slightly preferred to foreign ones. The existing \'erein tariff contains, together WMth the purely fiscal duties, a series of moderate protective duties intended to benefit certain branches of industry. The abolition or decrease of these duties does not appear advis- able, especially in the present position of industry. Perhaps, indeed, it would be well to re-introduce duties on a number of articles or to increase the present rates in the interest of various depressed branches of home industr}-, in accordance with the results of the investigation now in progress. Yet protective duties for individual industries, when they exceed the limit imposed by regard for their financial proceeds, act as a privilege and arouse on the part of representatives of unprotected industries the antipathy to which every privilege is exposed. A customs system which secures to the entire home production a preference before foreign production in the home market, while keeping within the limits imposed by financial interests, will not run the risk of this anti- pathy. Such a system will in no way appear partial, because its effects will be more equally spread over all the productive circles of the land than is the case with a system of protection for isolated branches of industry. The minority of the nation which does not produce at_ all, but exclusively consumes, will apparently be injured by a customs system favouring the entire national production. Yet if by means of such a system the aggregate sum of the values produced in the country increase and thus the national wealth P.G. F 66 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. be on the whole enhanced, the non-producing parts of the po])ulation — and especially the State and com- munal officials who are dependent upon a fixed money income — will eventually be benefited ; for means of counterbalancing hardships will be at the command of the community in case the extension of customs liability to the entire imports should result in an increase of the prices of the necessaries of life. Yet with low duties such an increase will in all probability not take place to the extent which consumers are accustomed to apprehend, just as, on the other hand, the prices of bread and meat have not fallen to an appreciable degree in consequence of the abolition of the duties on corn-grinding and cattle-killing in the parishes where these used to exist. The real financial duties, imposed on articles which are not produced at home, and the import of which is indispensable, will in part fall upon the consumer alone. On the contrary, with articles which the country is able to produce in quantity and quality adequate to the home consumption the foreign pro- ducer will alone have to bear the duty in order that he may compete in the German market. Finally in cases in which part of the home demand must be covered by foreign supply, the foreign producer will in general be compelled to bear at least a part, and often the whole of the duty, and thus to reduce his profit to the extent of this amount." Meantime, the Radicals and Free Traders — the "Manchester men" of that day — were on the alert. An Association for the Advancement of Free Trade {Vcrein zur Fordenmg der Hmidels- freiheit) was formed under the presidency of Dr. Bamberger, a member of the Reichstag and a high authority on finance. The first clause of its statute ran : — " The Association for the Ad- vancement of Free Trade seeks the maintenance THE TARIFF OF 1879. 67 of the measure of free international trade so far reached and its extension by means of commercial treaties," and in this sense it addressed a pressing memorial to the Federal Council on December 28th, 1878. The memorial came too late. With the publication of the Chancellor's letter the Govern- ment were committed, and from the position and policy therein outlined there was no with- drawal. In full sympathy with it was the speech from the throne which opened the following session of the Reichstag, on February 12th, 1879. " The Federal Governmenls," ran this utterance, " are considering legislative measures for the removal, or at least the diminution, of the economic evils from which we are suffering. The proposals which I have made, and still intend to make, to my allies aim, by providing the Empire with new sources of revenue, at placing the Governments in a position to desist from levying the taxes which they and their legis- latures recognise as the hardest to enforce. At the same time I am of opinion that the country's entire economic activity has a right to claim all the support which the legislative adjustment of duties and taxes can afford, and which in the lands with which we trade is, perhaps, afforded beyond actual requirement. I regard it as my dut_y to adopt measures to preserve tlie German market to national production so far as is consistent with tlie general interest, and our customs legislation must accordingly revert to the tried principles upon which the prosperous career of the ZoUverein rested for nearly half a century, but which have in important particulars been deserted in our mercantile policy since 1865. I cannot admit that actual success has attended this change in our customs policy." F 2 68 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. A few days later (February 21st) Prince Bis- marck reconnoitred the ground on the occasion of a discussion of a projected commercial treaty with Austria-Hungary. It should be said that the treaty of March, 1868, between that country and the old ZoUverein had been denounced in October, 1876. It had contained reciprocal ameliorations of the general tariffs of the contracting States, but Austria had declined to renew it on the old basis. On December i6th, 1878, the treaty was prolonged for one year pending the settlement of a new treaty and its due ratification by the Reichstag. The treaty was accepted, but the discussions to which it gave rise covered a far wider area. The entire question of fiscal policy was thrown into the controversial arena, and was debated by both sides with a vigour and at times a bitterness which faithfully reflected the temper of national opinion. " I propose to return to the time-honoured ways of from 1823 to 1865," declared the Chancellor to the delight of the members of the Protectionist Economic Union, while Radical deputies like Bamberger, Lasker, and Richter joined issue in uncompromising spirit, predicting the ruin of German commerce and industry, and accusing Bismarck in sharp words of being a renegade. Outside there was the same ferment, the same passion, the same resolute contest of forces which recognised that a fateful issue hung in the balance. Combination was answered by com- bination, manifesto by manifesto, demonstration THE TARIFF OF 1879. 69 by demonstration. On the Free Trade side the ' most striking pubhc protest was that of a congress of representatives of all the large towns in the Empire, held in Berlin on May 17th. That, too, was unavailing. Before this a Bill had been laid before the House on lines recommended by the Tariff Committee of the Federal Council, and the Chancellor, with un- wearied energ}', consummate tact, and marvellous resource, himself piloted it safely through the more than usually stormy waters of Parliamentary debate. In the speech with which he opened the discussion on the Bill on May 2nd, 1879, ^^^ said : — " The more I have gone into the question the more have I become convinced of the necessity and the urgency of reform. The present condition of German finance — by which I mean the finance not onl_v of the Empire but of the individual States as well — is such that in my opinion it imperatively calls for a speedy reform. The first motive which impels me in my political position as Im])erial Chancellor to enter upon such a reform is the need of the financial independence of the Empire. This need was recog- nised when the Imperial Constitution was drawn up. That Constitution presumes that the system of matri- cular contributions should be a temporary one, and should only last until Imperial taxes were introduced. . . . Certainly it is undesirable that the Empire should be a burdensome boarder or a dunning creditor, while it might be the liberal provider of the individual States if only proper use were made of the revenues which the Constitution put in the Empire's way, yet which hitherto have, been disregarded. To this" state 70 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of things I maintain an end should be made, since the matricular contributions are unjust in their distribu- tion. , . . The consolidation of the Empire after which we all strive will be furthered when these contribu- tions are replaced by Imperial taxes ; it would not lose if these taxes were so abundant that the individual States received from the Empire instead of giving to it as hitherto in a way not always computable and at the same time inconvenient. " A second reason why a change of the present system seems necessary lies in the question — Is the burden, which must necessarily be imposed in the interest of the State and the Empire, imposed in the form in which it can most easily be borne, or is it not ? This question must, according to my convic- tion, be answered in the negative. . . . We do not by any means seek for larger revenues in so far as the Reichstag and the Diets do not agree with us in voting expenditure to meet which income would have to be found. Indeed, I do not know what the Empire would do with a superabundance of money ; we had it when the French milliards came to us, and in the spending of them we got ourselves into a certain amount of perplexity. . . . We ask no more than we now have or than you and the Diets may be pleased to vote us ; but we do wish that that revenue which is proved necessary may be raised in the form in which it can be borne most easily by the taxpayers. The Federal Governments are convinced that indirect taxes — that source of revenue so long neglected by the ZoUverein — are the form in which the burden that we may have to bear will fall most lightly. . . ." And turning to the question of protection for industry : — " It is a reproach to our existing legislation . . . that the incidence of our indirect taxes does not afford to our national labour and production the measure of Protection which can be given to it without danger THE TARIFF OF 1879. 71 to the interests of the community. I am not going to enter into any contention about Protection and Free Trade. Hitherto we have all been Protectionists, even the greatest Free Traders amongst us, for no one has been wishful to go below the present tariff, which remains moderately protective, and such is also the proposal that we make to you. We ask for a moderate protection of national labour. We are far removed from any system of prohibition such as exists in most neighbouring countries, as, for example, in America, which was formerly our principal buyer, where the duties average from 60 to 80 per cent, ad valorem. All that we propose by way of Protection keeps within the limits of financial taxation except where the omis- sion of higher duties would entail great present injury upon larger classes of our fellow citizens." Casting doubt upon the probability of any further Free Trade development for years to come, he added : " The only exception is England, and that will not last long. France and America have both completely forsaken that direction. Austria, instead of reducing its protective duties, has increased them ; Russia has done the same, not only through the gold coinage, but in other ways. Therefore no one can expect Germany « to remain permanently the dupe of an honest convic- tion. Hitherto the wide-opened gates of our imports - have made us the dumping-place (Ablagevungsstdtte) of all the over-production of foreign countries. At present • they can deposit everything with us, and their goods, when once in Germany, have always a somewhat higher value than in the land of origin — at least our people think so — and it is the surfeiting of Germany with the over-production of other lands which most depresses our prices and checks the development of our industry and the restoration of our economic con- dition. Let us once close the door and erect the somewhat higher barriers which are proposed, and 72 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. let us see that we at any rate preserve the German market — that market which, thanks to our good nature, is now exploited by foreign lands — for German industry. The question of a great export trade is always exceedingly precarious. There are no longer any great countries to discover ; the globe is circum- navigated, and we cannot find any new mercantile nations of any great extent to which we can export. The policy of commercial treaties is, I grant, under certain circumstances very favourable, though when- ever such a treaty is concluded it is a question of Qui trompe-t-on ici? and it is only seen some years later who is really the victim." In a speech made on May 2ist, Prince Bismarck developed his views on agricultural protection. His thesis was that low corn prices were an unmixed evil, yet that the taxation of imports would leave the consumer no worse off, since the duty would be borne by the foreigner. Here he joined issue with Dr. Delbriick, his late colleague in the Ministry, who had contended that the duty would only have the effect of making corn dearer, without benefiting agriculture at all. " If cheap corn is the goal at which we have to aim we ought long ago to have abolished the land tax, since it burdens the corn-growing industry at home, which produces 400 million cwts., against the 27 or 30 millions which we import. But no one has ever thought of such a thing ; on the contrary, the tax has been gradually increased throughout all Germany, so far as I know, and in Prussia it has increased 30 per cent, since 1861, viz., from 30 to 40 millions." It was his ideal to secure to the farmers a certain sale for their corn by closing the markets THE TARIFF OF 1879. 73 against the foreigner. He regarded as unjust a system under which agriculturists were on an average taxed for State and communal purposes to the extent of 20 per cent, of their incomes, and yet, owing to the free admission of corn, foreign countries were enabled to cripple them at every turn. " It is not our intention to require of the entire corn consumed a higher financial obligation than now. All we intend to do is to commute a part of the direct taxes which now fall on the agriculturist into the form, if you will, of a duty on consumption levied on the frontier, and there imposed on foreign corn, so that there will not necessarily be an increase in the price of the entire com supply, but only a slight attempt at compensatory justice in view of the dis- advantages under which the producers of corn have hitherto suffered at home as agai-nst the exemption from taxation and other privileges which foreign corn producers enjov. I am of opinion that this duty will have no influence on prices, but while the previous speaker (Dr. Delbruck) would regard that as a good fortune which he dare not anticipate, I contemplate it wiih a certain regret, for I must ask myself the question : Is not the moment approaching when our agriculture will no longer be able to exist because corn is pressed down to a price at which it cannot be remuneratively produced in Germany ; taxation, the cost of living, and the debts on land being as they are ? When that moment comes, then not only agri- culture but the Prussian State and the German Empire will go to ruin as well. . . . But I need not picture the way in which agriculture, and with it our State and national existence, might decay, for it will not happen ; twenty million German farmers will not allow themselves to be ruined ; it is only necessary that they should become conscious of what is before them, and they will seek to defend themselves by all legal and constitutional means," 74 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. So, too, he defended the timber duties on the ground that they would keep out Russian and Swedish wood, and enable the home forester to earn a tolerable return without being under the necessity of hacking down all his trees in order to make ends meet. But whether the interest to be protected was agriculture or forestry or industry, the one thing certain was that nobody would be injured, but everybody benefited. The foreigner would, as a matter of course, bear the duties on industrial imports, and as for corn the home country would grow all that was needed without anyone having to pay a penn}^ more. Deputy Delbriick, the ex-Minister, calculated that the corn duties would actually cost the army administration more than they would bring to the treasury in revenue, but at that time the Chancellor's theory of the incidence of taxation held the charmed ear of country party and town party alike, and Delbriick could only challenge the verdict of experience. It is superfluous to follow the fortunes of the Tariff Bill before it emerged from debate, a com- pleted measure, very much in the form proposed by the Government, whose difficulty in the then constitution of parties was not to persuade the Reichstag to adopt Protection sufficient but to persuade it to be moderate in its demands. It was inevitable, too, that interest should have played against interest in the universal scramble for gain. Referring to the insidious way in V THE TARIFF OF 1879. 75 which this was done, Professor Walther Lot2 writes : " Deputy Fliigge characterised the negotiations which led to the increase of the majority and to the strengthening of Protection in words which are very familiar : ' If, (he said) the members present were behind the scenes in the House during the negotia- tions over the iron duties, then perhaps they had the same experience as 1 when I saw the " honourable brokers " come in. The one bid, " If you will give 50 for rye I will give you a full iron duty," or, " If you will reject von Weddell's amendment I will give you the rye duty," and so forth. Gentlemen, one doubted at the time whether one was not in the Leipzig Street rather than in an otherwise so honour- able assembly as this.' " Lotz himself adds : " Eye- witnesses assure us that very American-like methods were used at that time in the land of poets and thinkers, that in order to strengthen the majority for the entire tariff protective duties were bandied about very liberally so long as the desire for them could be realised without offence to powerful interests. It was said, indeed, upon the Opposition side that the German Hamlet had become a Richard III." ^ The Bill received Imperial assent on July 7th, 1879, and under it part of the new tariff came into operation at once, part on October ist, 1879, and the remainder on January ist, 1880. All the duties imposed were intended to be revenue- producing, though some articles were singled out for special taxation on account of their proved productiveness, such as Colonial goods, and 1 " Die Ideen der deutschen Handelspolitik von i860 bis 1891" (pp. 169 and 174), Dr. Walther Lotz, Leipzig, 1892. 76 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. especially coffee and tea, with petroleum, tobacco, wines, and spirits. The corn duties were fixed as follows : Wheat, rye, oats and legumes .. Barley, maize and buckwheat Malt Rape and rapeseed Anise, coriander, fennel, cummin Per ton. I OS. I2S. 30S. Of industrial raw materials, cotton, wool, ores, and earths were admitted free. Upon manu- factured and partly manufactured goods the following duties were imposed : Per ton. Cotton yarn (according to number) £^ to ^24. Carded wool • ■ ■ £^- Woollen yarn • # • £1 lOS. Cotton goods, rough and bleached ... • • • £40- Knitted goods • • • ' £^0. Pig-iron • • ■ I OS. Manufactured iron • • • 25s. to 30S. Rough iron and steel goods • . * i^i 5s-to ^3. Fine • • • iri2. Sewing needles • • • £30. Musical instruments • • • £15- Machinery • • • il I OS. to £4,. Common glass « • • £1 10s. Fine glass ware • • • A to £5. Scientific instruments of every kind were admitted free, as also sea and river-going vessels with their machinery, furniture, and utensils. Grateful for the success of a cherished scheme of his own, the Emperor William, who was more THE TARIFF OF 1879. 77 Protectionist than his Chancellor, wrote to the latter from Mainau on July 20th : " I must now congratulate you on the victory you have gained in the Reichstag on the question of the customs tariff reform. To your many outside victories must now be added this one on internal financial questions. You undertook to stir up a wasps' nest, and I sided with you from conviction, although I feared the result of your enterprise. It is rare that such a complete change of public opinion has been achieved in such a short time, and one sees that after immense work and effort you hit the right nail on the head. Some damage may have been done in the process, but a majority of 160 votes is a triumph which will sweeten many of your bitter hours of preparation and fighting. The Fatherland will bless you for this, although the Opposition may not do so." 78 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER VI. THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. Germany has often been blamed — and most of all by her own writers — for the entire Protectionist reaction which took place in the 'eighties. Refer- ring to the movement for the commercial federa- tion of the British Empire and its danger for German foreign trade, Dr. Eugen Moritz writes : " But this danger has almost been provoked by the policy which has for many years been followed in Germany, since the policy of high protective duties whose foundation Bismarck laid in 1879 became for all other States in the world either an example worthy of imitation or a terrible warning, so that some of them surrounded themselves likewise with a system of high duties and others endeavoured to form themselves with their colonies into complete territorial unities." There is justice in the accusation. With Germany's return to Protection began a general reaction which speedily spread over the Continent, and passed thence to the United States and to the British Colonies, deriving impetus and strength as it progressed. Russia increased her duties in 1881 and 1882, Austria and France did the same 1 " Eisenindustrie, Zolltarif, und Aussenhandel," Berlin, 1903. THE SUPPLEMENTARY Tx\RIFFS. 79 in the latter 3'ear, and it was not long before customs barriers rose on all hands to a height hitherto unknown. England alone showed an undisturbed faith in the policy of a free market. Meantime Germany's first experiences of her new tariff were not in general encouraging. In the inevitable conflict of interests which was waged over the Bill in Parliament, when everybody wanted something, and was suspicious lest he should be left out in the cold, it happened necessarily that calculations miscarried. For the protection of one industry proved the prejudice of another. It was not to the interest of the producer of raw materials that the industrialist should be able to obtain his wool, his skins, and his ores from abroad as cheaply as possible, nor was it, on the other hand, to the interest of the industrialist that the home stock breeder, miner, and maker of chemicals and dyeing stuffs should command artificial prices, so making dearer the final pro- cesses of manufacture. Those who knew clearly what they wanted and had succeeded in getting it, those who had obtained protection for their monopolies, were well satisfied with the bargain which had been struck, but for a time discontent was wide spread, and disillusionment not uncommon. In the iron trade prices fell in spite of the duties, while in the textile trade the higher duties on yarns led to less work and decreased exports owing to dearer production. One man's medicine was often enough another man's poison. 8o PROTECTION IN GERMANY. "What influence," asked the report for iSSi of the Diisseldorf Chamber of Commerce, " has the new customs tariff, which entered into full force at the beginning of this }ear, had on production and prices ? As to this point we can, on the authority of a searching investigation in industrial circles, assert with satis- faction that the influence of the tariff has in general been favourable for the industries of this district. The balance sheets of the larger establishments and the increase of the number of workpeople are visible evidence of it. It is true that some concerns still com- plain of the great foreign competition : yet they do not oppose the principle of the new customs system, but rather regard the protection given as insufficient. Nevertheless, we will not ignore the fact that many industries which use raw materials and half-manu- factured goods from abroad are for the time worse off under the tariff, but no economic reform is conceivable without injury to individuals." So, too, the Elberfeld Chamber of Commerce reported : " It is unmistakable that individual branches of manufacture have been favourably influenced, par- ticularly in the home market, though on the contrary others, and especially those which have to procure their raw material and half-manufactured goods from abroad, have to contend with great difficulties, so far as the export trade goes." One curious miscalculation deserves to be noted. The Government originally proposed to schedule flax amongst the free imports, but, in the prevalent rage for protection, comprehension was judged the only safe principle, and it was saddled with a duty of ten shillings per ton. Directly the tariff came into force, however, it was found that the flax duty would not work at all, and a special Act THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 8i of Parliament was passed in April, 1880, repealing it. In the same way the soap and perfumery industry promptly petitioned for the removal of the duties on tallow and oil ; the machine trades found that the dearer pig-iron and steel obtained from England made it difficult to compete in foreign markets; and the clothing trade, which produced largely for abroad, declared itself to be hopelessly handicapped. In some cases the duties were found to be useless, as there was no competi- tion to be kept out. Certainly there was a quick increase in the export trade and a corresponding decline in the imports of manufactured goods, as the following figures show : — Iron and iron goods ... Instruments, machines, and vehicles Raw lead, copper, tin, zinc, and rolled zinc Leather and leather goods Silk goods Yarn, rope, woven and knitted goods of linen, cotton and wool Paper and cardboard goods Colonial goods and comestibles Imports. Exports. 1878. 1880. I 1878. 1880, In 1,000,000 Marks. 67-0 34-8 307 3i'3 39'6 213-8 47 148-2 28-8 15-6 27'3 24-6 26-5 189-9 3'3 84-4 570-1 1 395-5 157-3 I 177-4 74-1 1 79-3 50-3 ! 47-3 69-9 70-3 354"? 17-9 ^y^-5 1926-5 125 1 181-4 4i3"2 2,19-1 1368-3 P.G. 82 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. eThus, while the exports of industrial goods increased in two years 341-8 million marks, or 33 per cent., the imports decreased i74'6 million marks, or 31 per cent. Nevertheless, the immediate prosperity which was promised to the working classes does not appear to have been realised. The Conservative party's programme of 1880 had to confess that " 400,000 work-people roam the highways idle and unable to find employment." " The working man," wrote a Frankfurt journal a little later, " was promised a fowl in his pot ; he has not got the fowl, and it is likely that he will lose the pot as well." There were moderate increases of wages in many industries, but they were not equal to the increased cost of living. A report of the Association of Iron and Steel Manufacturers, based on returns of 305 smelting works, foundries, and machine building works, set forth that while the average weekly wages on January ist, 1880, were 15s. 3^. per w^eek, they were only 165.4^. a year later. Colliers' wages (hewers) in Westphalia only increased from 15s. 5^. in 1878—79 to 15s. yd. in 187^—80, and by 1884 to i6s. ; while in Silesia they were long unchanged and only reached 15s. by 1885. Referring to the effect of the high price of corn in 1881, when it stood at over £10 a ton, against £6 los. before the duties were introduced, Dr. Karl von Scherzer wrote : — " While the duties fall exclusively on the consumers there are no evidences whatever that with the dearer THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 83 price of the articles of daily consumption the wages of labour liave correspondingly increased. ... In 1878 and 1879 the average minimum and maximum wages in the most various industries of France ranged from 1 6s. to 28s., in England from 20s. to 33s., in New York from 30s. to loos., in Chicago from 22s, to 36s., 24s. to 42s., and Cos. to lOos. ; but in Germany they were iis. Sd., 12s. 6f/., and i8s. lod. Moreover, in most of the countries named, the articles of daily- use, like flour, bread, beef, milk, cheese, coal, &c., were cheaper than in Germany. Since the coming into operation of the new customs tariff this relation- ship has not become more favourable for Germany. The prices of food are still dearer, and the wages of labour have either not increased at all or have not increased in the same proportion, while in France, England, and especially America, wages have greatly increased during the last ten years. In these countries, too, the purchasing power of the mass of the people, which is of material importance for the sale of industrial products, has increased, while in Germany it has considerably diminished."^ The immediate effect of the corn duties had been a general fall in prices, due to the excessive imports and the over - speculation which had preceded the introduction of the tariff. When, however, an equilibrium had been regained prices speedily increased to a height unknown for years. Yet the predictions of both Protectionists and Free Traders were in some respects singularly falsified. The former had justified the corn duties by the low prices which had ruled for a long time. These prices were attributed to foreign competi- tion, facilitated by cheap means of transport, and ^ " Wirthschaftliche Thatsachen zum Nachdenken," Leipzig, 1881. G 2 84 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. it was contended that Protection would alone prevent a still more disastrous decline. At that time the price of rye in the port of Bremen was under £6 los. per ton. Yet, though the new duty on rye was only los., the price in the same market rose to ;^8 5s. in 1880 and to ;^io in 1881. It was proved also that there never was more corn in the country than was required for the satisfaction of national needs, so that there was no question of retaining the home market for the home producers. In the first year of the tariff the foreign corn trade was as follows : — Excess of Imports. Exports. Imports. Tons. Tons. Tons. Wheat . .. 227,542 . .. 178,17^^ ... 49,366 Rye .. 689,598 . .. 26,586 .. 663,012 Barley 222,261 . .. 154,409 ... 67,852 Oats .. 161,686 . • 43.577 .. 118,109 Maize .. 340,640 . 1,369 .. 339,271 1,641,727 404,117 1,237,610 As before, just half of the total excess of imports fell to rye, the staple food of the people. The extent to which the corn grower benefited in these early years is difficult or impossible to determine, though opinions agree that the small farmer, at any rate, gained nothing. For the fall in corn prices, when it came, was not for a long time accompanied by a proportionate fall in the value of the land and in rents, and to prevent that was the aim of the agrarian party. Both in the Eastern and Western Provinces of Prussia rents THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 85 increased even on the fiscal domains with new tenancies between 1880 and 1884, and only after 1885 did a decline set in. In Silesia there was no change, and in Pomerania, Brandenburg, and Posen there was a fall. On the other hand, in the Grand Duchy of Baden land values rather increased than decreased during the period 1868 to 1888, while leasehold rents declined. It is interesting, at this distance of time, to recall the fact that before Protection had been in force three years the Government for a time seemed to waver and weigh the wisdom of revision. In August of 1883 the Reichstag was convened in extraordinary session to confirm a commercial • treaty with Spain. This treaty proposed a sub- stantial reduction of duties, and hopeful Liberals saw in it the sign of a disposition to return to the Delbruck policy of " conventional tariffs." Both sides gave and took — Spain had the duties on wine, oil, rye, fruits, lead, iron and copper ores, skins and furs, and cork goods modified in her favour, and Germany received concessions in respect of iron and steel goods, woollen yarns, aniline dyes, and other products. There wasj reciprocity, but it did not go far. Twelve years were to pass, and another Minister was to come to the helm, before the pressure of the tariff was to be eased all round, and meantime it was for a second and a third time made more severe. In 1884 Prince Bismarck publicly claimed that Protection had ** freed the country from economic 86 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. pressure,'' and that its prosperity was steadily increasing. Imports and exports were both advancing, and there was in ever}- port more shipping ; though that drooping flower of the national garden, agriculture, had not yet lifted up its head. In truth wheat in 1885 was lower in price than for 30 years, and rye much below the average. The movement of corn prices may best be shown by a comparison : — Pric€ ; per Ton. Wheat. Rye. Barley. Oats, i s. d. £ ^■ d. £ s. d. £ s. d. 1878 ... 10 7 3 0: 7 17 6 19 1879 ... 9 16 7 4 0! 7 8 6 14 1 8S0 (first year 10 19 9 19 01 8 8 7 12 of duties). 1 1881 II 10 2 o| 8 6 7 19 1882 ... 10 8 8 I 7 14 740 1883 ... 9 5 7 7 7 6 ° 6 17 Average for six years. £^0 5 £S 6 o!i:7 16 6| £744 It was estimated at that time that the cost of production of a ton of wheat averaged in all Prussia £(^ los., varying from £$ 17s. 6d. in the far East to ;^io los. in the South (Province of Saxony), while the price was in some markets £^ and even less. Even on the intensive farms of Thuringia corn could not be grown for less than £"9 17s. bd., and it only brought the grower £8. THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 87 Not only so, but the corn imports had further increased. The following were the imports and exports in 1884 as compared with 1878 : — In tons. 187S. In tons. 1S84. Wheat Rye.. .. Barley Oats.. Maize Imports. 1,055,000 945,000 434,500 290,000 114,000 Exports. 785,000 196,000 266,000 134.500 20,650 Excess of Imports. 270,000 749,000 168,500 155,500 93,350 Imports. 582,530 842,530 433,540 365,960 191,990 Exports. 36,190 6,280 37,260 18,520 410 Excess of Imports. 546,340 836,250 396,280 347,440 191,580 Totals . . 2,838,500 [ 1,402,150 1 1,436,350 2,416,550 98,660 2,317,890 And while the farmer had not been benefited there was no pretence that his labourers had fared better. Once more the cry for help was raised by this depressed industry ; alike in the Reichstag and the federal Legislatures there w^as constant talk of *' threatened existences " and urgent appeal to the all-powerful State to complete the good work of relief and redemption which it began five years before. Prince Bismarck did not hesitate to respond to the call. Early in 1885 he introduced a Bill revising the tariff on both sides. The expose des motifs which accompanied it claimed that the law of 1879 " has in general been attended by beneficial results for our economic life," and that the country's " economic development has been diverted from a false course into one which will enable energetic and discerning effort to com- pete successfully with other countries both in the home and foreign markets." 88 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. It was held, however, that '' a natural develop- ment and improvement " of the tariff was neces- sary to the better attainment of the goal then chosen. Once again Prince Bismarck stepped into the arena and championed the cause of Pro- tection against its critics, boldly claiming that, in spite of the necessity for severer duties, the existing tariff had worked well according to its limitations. Agriculture was, as before, his special concern. " The fear has been expressed," he said on February loth, 1885, "that the price of corn will in consequence of the higher duties increase very con- siderably, and that social dangers will thus arise. Well, you will remember that six years ago the same prophecies were made in this very hall, and in part by the men who have spoken to-day or who will yet speak. We were told that prices would reach such a height that they would curtail the labourer's earnings and food, and that we were inviting the social dangers which we desired to resist and remove. All these prophecies have proved false ; not one of them has been fullilled. The corn laws of that time have everywhere worked beneficently. Only in one direction have they proved ineffective where the reverse was perhaps expected, though not by me, for I thought otherwise : they have not had the effect of improving the prices of agricultural produce. On the contrary, corn is now cheaper than it has been for a long time, and in proportion to the present value of money cheaper than it has ever been this century. The effect then predicted has in no way been produced. Whether it will be produced when the duty is trebled I will not venture to say with certainty, though I hardly think it probable. It may, however, be the case, and if it is, well and good, for the farmer will benefit by an increase in prices ; but if not, the duties will certainly be borne by foreign THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 89 countries, and why should not the Finance Minister of the German Empire accept the duties which America and Russia are willing to pay him ? . . . In any case I should rejoice if the law led to an increase of prices, for the improvement of the position of the farmers would be far from injuring others. " I hope that the price of corn may increase. I hold its increase to be necessary. There must be a limit when the State must try to raise the price of corn. Just you imagine the price of rye falling to 50 pfennige a hundredweight, or I will name the price which now and again really occurs in the inner Russian Governments, the price of one mark. Is it not quite clear that our agriculture would then be absolutely ruined — that it would not be able to exist any longer — and with it all the labourers and all the capitalists dependent upon it? Quite apart from the farmer — who is, of course, a corpus vile on which the town folk can experiment, tliough it must be remembered that the towns would no longer have bu3-ers in the farmers — the labourers would be with- out employment and would stream to the towns. In short, it is undoubtedly a national calamity when the price of corn, the everyday means of subsistence, falls below the rate at which it can be cultivated with us, I will regard the maxim as admitted, that there is a limit below which the price of corn cannot fall without the ruin of our entire economic life. The question then is : Has this limit been reached or not ? Minister Lucius has given us statistics which must compel us to admit that it has already been reached. Rut it should not be reached ; for when it is reached it will be too late, and we shall already have suffered most enormous losses. . . . When rye with us falls to a price at which it cannot be cultivated, we are living in unsound conditions and are going to decay. This decay may be deferred by the use of the capital we may have laid up, but that we create an unte- nable situation is as clear as that two and two make four." Bismarck was, as we have seen, quite correct in claiming that the price of corn had not increased, but it is fair to add that the duties deserved no thanks for this, since Germany still paid more for her grain than non-protected countries. The Bill increased the duties on timber and wood ware also, and on a number of industrial articles, chiefly laces and silks. It passed through its various stages without serious opposition, and was Anally accepted on May 13th by a large majority (igg to 105), made up for the most part of the old comrades in arms, the Conservatives, Clericals and National Liberals. The important alterations in the tariff were the following, the duties being per ton : — Tariff. 1879 d. 1885 £ 5. d. Wheat 10 I 10 Rye Oats 10 10 I 10 15 Buckwheat 10 10 Legumes 10 10 Barley ... Rape and rapeseed Maize 5 3 5 15 10 10 Malt 12 I 10 Ground grain ... I 10 ••• 3 15 Timber (where altered) Laces IS. to 6 5 15s. 2S. to ... 8 15 £3 Silk knitted, and la ce clothing goods Ditto of half silk • • • 450 225 ... 600 •■■ 338 ^5 Artificial flowers ■ • ■ 150 ... 400 Sewing cotton ... ... 18 ■•• 35 v^ V^ J. X L 3^a Jk. ^ J. , Tarifif. Cocoa, chocolate, and 1879. £ 5. d. 1885. £ 5. d. surrogates Mineral oils Silk thread 40 o o 500 100 o o 30 o o 300, 50 10 o The duties on live stock were increased as follows : — Horses Mules and donkeys Cattle Oxen Calves Pigs Sheep Lambs Goats each 1879. £ s. d. 10 o ID O 4s. to 6s. 100 2 O 2 6 I o o 6 free 1885. £ s. d. I p o 10 p 5s. to 9s. I 10 o 3 o 6 o I o p 6 free The new tariff was thus essentially a sop to agriculture, and the higher duties given to industry were of the nature of an apology and a solatium. Indeed, it was not clear that industry desired them. The Hamburg Borsen Halle re- ported a curious incident : — "On the second reading the Clerical Deputy Trim- born brought forward a proposal to increase the duties on silk and half-silk goods ' in the interest of the Crefeld industry,' which, however, telegraphed an emphatic protest, so that on a vote no one, not even the proposer himself, supported these increased duties. In spite of this, the Protectionist Economic Union on the day for taking the third reading again brought forward various proposals for increasing the duties, and this time they were carried without time for 92 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. proper discussion being allowed. The Employers' Association of Crefeld had in the meantime, through questions put to its members, proved that ninety manufacturers, who through the importance of their business represented the great bulk of the Crefeld silk industry, were opposed to the increase, while only twenty-five pronounced in its favour." The only argument advanced in the Reichstag in support of higher duties was that fifty manu- facturers were " understood " to desire more pro- tection, while nearly twice the number actually petitioned against it. Nor afterwards was industry by any means cordial in appreciating the Government's unsought attentions. The Chamber of Commerce of Leip- zig, in their report for 1886, recalled with longing the restful era of Free Trade, when manufacturers and merchants, if unprotected, were at any rate free from disturbance and alarms. They uttered their "regrets at the continual proposals for the modi- fication of the customs tariff, which follow one another so rapidly that trade and industry have no longer that peace which is the first condition of a prosperous course of business relationships and of healthy economic development. , . . The degree to which the demands for protection against the natural development of things have graduallv advanced is illustrated by a petition addressed to" the Reichstag by the directors of the Pomeranian Agricultural Society asking, among other far-going claims, for an import duty of 100 marks per double cwt. of washed wool and one of from 60 to 80 marks on raw wool by means of a special emergency law in the interest of agriculture. ... It is more than questionable THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 93 whether the petitioners themselves would, even if their demand were granted, be disposed to increase their production of wool to any great extent. That German agriculture, which now only supplies about one-tenth of the total consumption of German industry, could ever again be able to produce the whole both in quantity and quality is inconceivable. A large part of German industry has been built upon the imports of foreign wool, and just as it buys most of its raw material abroad, so it sends abroad a large part of its products. Even the small cloth-making industry, which was formerly the principal customer of the German wool producers, is compelled to buy certain kinds of wool abroad. That the develop- ment of the German woollen industry has taken place at the expense of German sheep breeding is an entirely untenable assertion. The German farmers no longer find it to their interest to produce the kinds of wool which the prevailing factories require. So far as they carry on sheep breeding at all, they attach most importance to the production of meat, as being more remunerative." Other Chambers of Commerce received the Government's proposals more sympathetically, but the foregoing episode is a fair illustration of the difficulty which was experienced in conciliating conflicting interests. On the other hand, agriculture, which did desire * more Protection, was doomed again to disappoint- ment, for the higher duties were no more successful than the lower in arresting the fall of prices, which continued during the following two years, and reached their lowest point in Germany in 1887, in Austria and Hungary and Holland in 1888, and in England, Denmark and Russia in 1889. According 94 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. to the returns of the Prussian Statistical Office, the following were the average prices for the whole of the monarchy per ton : — Only in i8gi did a decided check set in. The late Professor Albert Schaffle, writing in 1892, thus described the operation of Protection up to that date : — " The quite extraordinary increase in land values from the middle of the 'lit'ties to the middle of the 'seventies greatly increased the prices of commodities and leasehold rents as well. When later a strong decline of the net return set in, it was not easy to fall in with the new condition of things. There lived and lives an entire generation of landowners who invested their capital in the land in the expecta- tion of higher net returns and have mortgaged them- selves in so doing. There were also a great many lessees whose eighteen-years' contracts ran on far into the lean years. The population had grown in the earlier favourable times ; a generation, increased in the meantime, is building up families now, indeed, when longer crises and even a condition of need are setting in, and it continually overpays both in land purchase and in rent. Large numbers have fallen into debt more or less in the mere purchase of their land, and the working funds which should have facilitated the transition to a more intensive culture and the necessary uivestments of capital are now THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 95 wanting. Nay, these funds are becoming less and less as reduced profits, and even deficits, have to be faced year after year, since losses and interest have consumed the capital itself. Hence the advice that they should immediately adapt themselves to the new conditions is in the case of many people rather superfluous. Those who are already up to the neck in water prefer to clutch greedily at the rope of monetary palliatives if such are offered."* Two years passed, and once more the agricul- tural party reminded the Government of their obligation, and 1887 saw a further increase of the corn and live stock duties. The duty upon wheat and rye was raised from £1 los. to £2 ids. per ton, a rate then equalled by no other European country. The duty in Spain was £2 2s. 6d. for wheat and £1 10s. lod. for rye, in France it was £2 and 8s. ^d. respectively ; in Austria-Hungary it was £1 lys. 6d. for both ; while in Russia, Roumania, Belgium and Holland, as in England, corn remained free. The duty on oats was increased from 15s. to £2 per ton, and that on buckwheat and legumes from los. to £1. Side by side with the protection given by the tariff the revision of the railway tariff was demanded at this time, so that the administrations of the important State lines might no longer neutralise the economic policy of the Government to the prejudice of agriculture. Soon another form of protection was sought and obtained in the form of 1 "Zur wissenschaftlichen Orientierung liber die neueste Handelspolitik," in Tiibingcr Ztitschrift, 1892. 94 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. to the returns of the Prussian Statistical Office, the following were the average prices for the whole of the monarchy per ton : — Wheat. Rye. Barley. Oats. Potatoes. Hay. £. s. d. £, s. d. C s. d. £ s. d. £ s. d. £ s. d. 1S71 -7. .11 5 8 19 8 II 8 S 300 3 12 r88i . . 1 II 10 2 860 7 19 2 17 3 14 1S82 . . 1 10 8 S I 7 14 7 4 290 3 9" 1883 . •'950 7 7 7 6 6 17 3 I 340 188.1 ■ . 1 8 13 770 790 7 4 290 3 I 1885 . .820 7 3 730 7 3 260 2 14 1886 . 7 17 6 14 6 15 6 13 210 300 1887 . 840 650 680 5 13 260 300 1888 . 8 14 6 15 6 15 6 10 2 12 380 i88q . 930 7 16 7 II 7 II 2 12 360 Only in i8gi did a decided check set in. The late Professor Albert Schaffle, writing in 1892, thus described the operation of Protection up to that date : — " The quite extraordinary increase in land values from the middle of the 'lifties to the middle of the 'seventies greatly increased the prices of commodities and leasehold rents as well. When later a strong decline of the net return set in, it was not easy to fall in with the new condition of things. There lived and lives an entire generation of landowners who invested their capital in the land in the expecta- tion of higher net returns and have mortgaged them- selves in so doing. There were also a great many lessees whose eighteen-years' contracts ran on far into the lean years. The population had grown in the earlier favourable times ; a generation, increased in the meantime, is building up families now, indeed, when longer crises and even a condition of need are setting in, and it continually overpays both in land purchase and in rent. Large numbers have fallen into debt more or less in the mere purchase of their land, and the working funds which should have facilitated the transition to a more intensive culture and the necessary mvestments of capital are now THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 95 wanting. Nay, these funds are becoming less and less as reduced profits, and even deficits, have to be faced year after year, since losses and interest have consumed the capital itself. Hence the advice that they should immediately adapt themselves to the new conditions is in the case of many people rather superfluous. Those who are already up to the neck in water prefer to clutch greedily at the rope of monetary palliatives if such are offered."* Two years passed, and once more the agricul- tural party reminded the Government of their • obligation, and 1887 saw a further increase of the corn and live stock duties. The duty upon wheat and rye was raised from £1 los. to £2 ids. per ton, a rate then equalled by no other European country. The duty in Spain was £2 2s. 6d. for wheat and ;^i los. 10^. for rye, in France it was £2 and 8s. 4^. respectively ; in Austria-Hungary it was £1 17s. 6d. for both; while in Russia, Roumania, Belgium and Holland, as in England, corn remained free. The duty on oats was increased from 15s. to £2 per ton, and that on buckwheat and legumes from los. to ;^i. Side by side with the protection given by the ' tariff the revision of the railway tariff was demanded at this time, so that the administrations of the important State lines might no longer neutralise the economic policy of the Government to the prejudice of agriculture. Soon another form of ^ protection was sought and obtained in the form of ' "Zur wissenschaftlichen Orientieriing iiberdie neueste Handelspolitik," in Tiihinger Zdtschrift, 1893. 96 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. veterinary measures aiming at the exclusion of foreign live stock, and with these the agrarians may be said to have avowed the egoism of their endeavours and to have reduced fiscal policy to a calculated system of direct State relief. And the result for the consumer ? Conrad has estimated that from 1851 to 1870 the price of wheat was ^2 2S. less per ton in Prussia than in England ; from 1871 to 1880 the difference had sunk to 3s. ; then from 1881 to 1885 the price in Prussia was gs. higher, from 1886 to 1889 it was £1 12s. higher, and in 1890 it was £2 4s. higher. In some parts of Germany the difference in 1889 was as much as £2 i8s., and in 1890 £^ 6s. Again, while in the later 'eighties the price of wheat in Prussia, Bavaria and Baden fell 12 per cent, as compared with 1879 to 1883, it fell in England 32 per cent., in Denmark 34, in Odessa 31, and in Pesth 29 per cent. So with oats, while the price before 1879 was more in England than in Prussia, it was equal in 1888; then in 1889 it was 13s. dearer in Prussia, and in 1890 it was ^i dearer. According to Matlekovits, the price of wheat increased in Germany with a duty of los. per ton (1879) ys. ; with one of £1 10s. (1885) £1 ; and with one of £2 los. (1887) £2, as compared with Free Trade countries generally. If the agriculturist, however, had to lament low prices, so also had the industrialist, and they con- tinued to decline from 1880 almost throughout the whole of the decade. According to Soetbeer THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARIFFS. 97 (Conrac I's" Jahrbucher," i8go),the prices of com- modities from 1882 to i88g compared as follows with those of 1881, the latter being taken as 100 : — Imports, Exports. In general. 1881 .. Index 100 ... Index 100 ... In dex 100 1882 .. 99-8 ... 1007 . 100-3 1883 .. 98-2 .. 98-5 98-4 1884 .. 93"3 •• 92-8 93-I 1885 .. 85-8 .. 85-8 85-8 18S6 .. 85-4 .. 83-8 84-6 18S7 .. 85-5 •• 83-5 84-5 1888 .. 85-4 .. 847 85-0 1889 .. 88-6 .. 87-2 87-9 The wages of the working classes, meantime, slightly increased, though less because of the "protection of national labour" than because of the higher cost of living, and even so the conces- sions made were rarely volunteered ; they were won by coalition and by strike. Moreover, dearer food, rising rents, and heavier taxation combined to nullify the advantage of freer earnings, and the actual condition of labour was no better. In 1891 and 1892 the cost of living was higher in Germany than ever since Protection was re-introduced. P.G. H 98 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER VII. THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. *' A CERTAIN weariness of the universal rivalry in national trade exclusiveness has now, after twelve years, set in, and that not only in trade, but even in industry, which more and more recognises that the modern protective system cuts both ways, and also amongst the Governments who struggle for commercial-political ' stability ' and would like to lower the barriers somewhat." So wrote in 1892 the late Professor Albert Schaffle, a political economist who was detached from all hide-bound theories of Free Trade and who never hesitated to defend protective measures as an educational expedient and as a means of staving off economic crises. It was a view of the position which had forced itself upon most thoughtful and disinterested observers, and not least upon the head of the Imperial Government himself — at that time Count von Caprivi. True, Germany had not gone so far in Protection as some other countries, save in her corn duties, for here only America and France equalled her. Taking European countries only, France could claim to be the most protected of all, then came Austria, then Italy, and Germany made a good fourth. Still, for her own interests THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 99 Germany had gone too far, and she had come to know it. The fruit of this knowledge was the series of commercial treaties which fell to the years ^' 1892-94, and which lasted until the end of 1903. Various moments combined to bring about a reaction against the exaggerated system of Protec- tion which had been built up in the course of twelve years. On the agricultural side it was attacked by those potent influences to which sec- tional legislation has again and again had to succumb — popular discontent and hostility. The year 1891 saw Germany exposed to a condition of ^ scarcity. The harvest had failed ; the price of corn rose to an alarming height ; hunger stalked through the streets gaunt and menacing. In Prussia the price of wheat between 1886 and 1890 averaged £8 15s. per ton ; in 1891 it rose to jTio i8s. Similarly the price of rye increased from £y 3s. during the preceding five years to j^io 4s. In Berlin the prices of these cereals rose to £"11 4s. and ;£"io IIS. respectively. " How will the introduction of a corn duty benefit the peasant class ? " asked an economic writer before the tariff of 1879 came into operation. "This duty has existed until twenty years ago, and when it was abolished no one shed a tear, and least of all the peasants. But even the great landowners should bear in mind that the corn duty was suspended at least in all years in which scarcity threatened, because the home harvest proved insufficient to feed our people, and that is the rule, for we cannot live without corn imports."^ » Karl Braun, " Der Staat und die Volkswirthschaft," 1879. H 2 loo PROTECTION IN GERMANY. Once more history repeated itself. The corn duties were suspended in the presence of an imminent famine, and so impressed were they by the anomaly of their position that the very leaders of the agrarian party in the Reichstag voted for the reversal of their own policy. It was the low corn prices of 1878 that made protective duties possible ; the high prices of 1891 made them for the time being impossible. Nevertheless, the crisis did not pass over without violence. Not since the memorable " March days " of 1848 had Berlin been the scene of such alarming popular demonstrations and riots as took place there in the closing days of February, 1902. Hunger and want of work were the main causes of the outbreaks, and for several days a veritable reign of terror prevailed in certain quarters of the city. Some of the streets fell into the hands of the mob ; shops and houses were looted ; property was destroyed wholesale ; ob- noxious persons were victimised ; the police were set at defiance ; and the wildest elements in the population for a time had things their own way. On the industrial side also the tariff had proved no less vulnerable, no less irksome, no less imprac- ticable. " The system of a general State guarantee, by means of customs duties, of industrial interest and agricultural rent," wrote Schaffle in 1892, '* has not succeeded, but has disappointed almost all the expectations based upon it." Germany's foreign trade had greatly increased — her imports between 1881 and i8go advancing from 14,800,000 THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. loi tons, of value £"114,500,000, to 28,100,000 tons, of value 3^213,600,000, and her exports from 16,600,000 tons, of value ;£*i52,ooo,ooo, to 19,300,000 tons, of value £"170,450,000 — but it was impossible to attribute this increase to Pro- tection. " So far as the effect of the increased industrial duties in their protective aspect goes," said the same writer, " while they have not prevented the growth of imports, they have had but the slightest demonstrable influence on the increase of exports. Even without these duties it is doubtful whether the movements of imports and exports would have taken a different form." Examining the course of trade in various staple industries during the 'eighties, Schaffle came to the following conclusions. We have seen that it was the assumed needs of two great industries, the iron and textile industries, which gave to the protective movement its strongest impetus. After ten years of a severe tariff it was found that imports and exports equally had increased in some branches of these industries and had decreased in others. The imports of pig-iron in 1881 were 244,601 tons, and though they fell 157,162 tons in i88g it was to rise again to 385,328 tons in i88g. The imports of malleable bar-iron increased from 14,198 to 28,942 tons. For a time the imports of iron wire and iron goods generally fell, but by 1890 they had exceeded the amount of 1881 to the extent of 100, 150, 200, and (in the case of fine wire) 400 per cent. The exports of angle iron, railway rails, sleepers, and 102 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. plates, and both rough and fine iron goods^ increased, though not equally. The value of the exports of iron wire fell from £2,200,000 in 1881 to £900,000 in 1890. Schaffle claims that neither the import nor the export movement in this industry can be called in evidence in support of Protection. " It is notorious that the iron rings and rail cartels, which were favoured by the protective system, compelled even the railway administrations at times to purchase abroad." The same story was told by the textile trade. The imports of cotton yarn increased from 16,475 tons in 1881 to 18,808 tons in 1890, though in some intervening years they were still more, while the exports fell from 18,371 tons to 7,180 tons, and at times even lower. The imports of cotton goods increased from 1,392 tons to 1,462 tons, with fluctuations in the interval, and the exports of heavy goods increased from 14,460 tons to 15,458 tons. "This movement in the cotton yarn and cotton goods trade would perhaps have been the same even without the revision of the tariff in 1879. In any case it has not pro- moted any special development of the trade, while on the contrary it has, by inviting tariff retaliation, more and more led to decreased exports, and by inducing over-production has caused crises in the home market." The imports of woollen yarn and woollen goods increased slightly between 1882 and 1890, the exports very largely. " Here the protective duties were of THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 103 some effect, though in the end it was greatly neutrahsed by foreign retahation." Of hnen yarn and linen goods there was an increased import until 1885, when the duties were increased, and after then a decline. The exports of the same increased considerably in quantity, but little in value. Finally, the imports of the silk trade increased but little, while the exports fell off slightly. Schaffle adds by way of summary : — " The position of these two great branches of industry showed unquestionably in 1890 a greater export capacity. The imports of finished iron manu- factures of all kinds had a value of i8'4 million marks, and the exports one of 1587 millions. The imports of textiles of all kinds had a value of only 46*4 million marks, and the exports one of 425"2 millions ; the imports of hosiery had a value of i'7 million marks, and the exports one of 1067 millions ; the imports of dress goods, finished personal linen, and millinery a value of 5"2 million marks, and the exports one of i2i"3 millions. It would, however, be very presumptuous to ascribe this to Protection. At the end of the fifteen years' epoch of Free Trade the exports of iron manufactured and half-manufactured goods and of finished textile goods increased likewise far beyond the imports." Coming to smaller industries, the imports of glass largely increased in quantity and for the most part in value as well, while the exports increased to a greater degree both as to quantity and value. The same thing happened in the case of musical instruments, also of rubber goods, "but certainly not in consequence of the protective system." The imports of cork goods largely increased, the exports were stationary. The exports of leather and leather goods decreased, but the contrary was the case with paper and paper goods. The imports of porcelain increased more than the exports, while both the imports and exports of earthenware increased. The imports of watches increased four-fold in value, while the exports of clocks largely increased. On the whole, Schaffle concludes, the imports increased in hardly less degree than the exports, and towards the end of the first decade of Protec- tion there was a falling off in many classes of exports due to the retaliation of foreign countries. The effect of Protection upon agriculture so far had been a negative one, for the price of corn had greatly decreased, while the corn grower had no greater monopoly of the home market than before. The imports of wheat increased from 1881 to 1900 from 391,949 to 672,587 tons, and the exports fell from 53,338 to 206 tons, with fluctuations in the intervening years. The imports of rye increased from 575,454 to 879,903 tons, and the exports fell from 11,564 to 119 tons. The imports of oats were fairly stationary, and the exports sank from 31,591 to 451 tons. Before duties were re-intro- duced, in 1875, 473,500 tons more wheat and rye were imported than were exported ; in 1881 (the first annual year after the duties came into force) the excess was 957,858 tons; in 1889 it was 1,574,247 tons. As to other branches of THE COMMEKCIAJL i KEATY EKA. 105 agriculture, the prices of live stock and of meat increased all round during the 'eighties, and that not only absolutely, but relatively to other countries which were either without Protection or did not increase their duties during that decade after Germany's example. Schaffle's general conclusion was as follows : — " That Germany's national production has been prejudiced under this system cannot be concluded from the available figures ; it has in nearly all branches been developed. Whether, however, in spite of or because of protective duties is a point upon which whole columns of controversy might be written. So far as positive proofs are possible in special cases it cannot be denied that the protective system is able successfully to promote trade and pro- duction. . . . On the other hand, we are as opposed now as before to the restrictive application of Pro- tection in the sense of early theory and practice, that is, beyond actually demonstrable needs, and a very different conclusion must be drawn when we consider the effect of the general protection of all branches of national production and trade, amounting to a universal State guarantee of industrial interest and agricultural rent, which has been claimed since 1879. The best that can be said is that our foreign trade, including that in manufactures, has neither in import nor export stood still, but this fact must not as a matter of course, if at all, be claimed to the credit of the system of high Protection. The transit trade and the commission trade in corn, timber, and colonial goods have unquestionably, and in part irremediably, suffered, and with them the railway returns. Industry has on the whole prospered in a gratifying measure, but so it did during the fourteen years of Free Trade prior to 1879. Isolated textile duties, particularly those in the interest of the fine cotton and linen io6 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. spinning industry, have proved a fiasco. The aim of supplying our own needs in corn and timber at home has as little been attained as the stability in prices and rents which was expected from the protective system and indeed predicted of it. Agriculture is more in debt than ever under this system. The imports of cattle have largely declined, but so also have the exports, in part perhaps to the advantage of more intensive cattle breeding and meat farming, but in part with certainty to the injury of agriculture itself." If it be objected that these statements refer to a past decade, and deal with matters of ancient history, the answer is that they have been recalled because of their direct bearing upon the com- mercial treaty policy inaugurated by Count von Caprivi. The true verdict upon the tariffs of 1879, 1885, and 1887 is contained in the simple fact that the welfare of German industry required in 1892 that the protective barriers should be lowered. However trade had developed at home, >J the effect of Protection abroad had been to bring about the old condition of " war of all against all." Directly one country revised its duties its neighbours retaliated. Russia and America had -si virtually closed their doors altogether to the out- side world, the latter by the McKinley Tariff of October 6th, 1890, and Russia by her tariff of July, 1901. In England also the growth of the ■•i Colonial federation movement gave rise in German minds to the apprehension that one of the most promising of markets might soon be placed under embargo. The uncertainty of international trade, THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 107 the perpetual unrest, and the indefinite fears as to the future conspired to make the German com- mercial world not merely ready but willing to bargain with any country which was prepared to meet concession by concession. It was found, in fact, that tariff warfare was the least practical of all methods of promoting the essentially pacific pursuit of trade. Speaking in the Reichstag on December loth, 1901, the Chancellor said : — " In this everything that has been written on industry agrees, from the scientific text book to the reports of the Chambers of Commerce, that the first require- ment of every industry is stability, that it may know what are the conditions with which it has to deal." It is the great merit of Count von Caprivi to have recognised the weakness of the fiscal system which he had inherited and to have had the courage to modify it according to the altered conditions and needs of his day. Germany had had commercial treaties for a generation, but the treaties of the Caprivi regime marked a novel departure from past custom. The old treaties "^ were based on fixed, invariable, autonomous tariffs, and most of them included the " most- favoured-nation " clause ; the new ones, while con- taining this clause, were based on " conventional " tariffs, each with certain limitations created ad hoc as the result of special bargaining with the State affected. Germany had hitherto received on the whole better terms than she had given. For io8 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. example, Roumania and Servia did not even enjoy most-favoured treatment. Again, Italy had in 1883 conceded to Germany the reduced rates already given by treaty to Austria and France without receiving much in return. The Spanish treaty of July i2th, 1883, and the Greek treaty of July 4th, 1884, were also in Germany's favour. In his treaty-making the "honest broker" had exacted a rather high commission, and many of the patrons who remained on his successor's books were dissatisfied with the terms. In 1891 most of the existing treaties, which included nearly all European States, would expire, and some of these States — Russia, Italy, Switzer- land, and Spain— in anticipation of the necessity of concluding new ones, had already notified their intention to increase their tariffs. It was either a case of renewed retaliation or reciprocity, and Caprivi chose reciprocity. In December, i8gi, J. the Chancellor laid before the Reichstag a series of treaties, with Austria-Hungary, Italy, Switzer- land, and Belgium, intended to come into force on February ist, 1892, and to last until December 31st, 1903, and thereafter from year to year unless either of the contracting States notified its desire to withdraw twelve months beforehand. They ^ all introduced the most-favoured-nation clause, and by special tariffs fixed the duties on both sides for the entire period of twelve years. In every case there was mutual concession, even to J the extent of admitting some articles free of duty. THE, COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 109 In their expose des motifs, published on December 7th, the Government enforced the necessity for J stabihty and security of foreign trade, which they admitted to be impossible under existingconditions, and urged the Reichstag to accept these four treaties in the behef that they would ensure more harmonious commercial relationships with an immense market specially interesting, owing to the geographical circumstances, to German enter- prise. Reviewing the events which had led to the adoption of the reciprocity treaty polic)', the Government said : — " The commercial and customs policy of Europe has in the last decade been regulated by a far- reaching system of tariff conventions, of which the treaties of France with Belgium, Portugal, and Norway were the starting point. Italy, Austria, and other nations some time later joined the movement and entered into treaties by which the customs tariffs were laid down for a number of years. Germany, however, had taken but little part in the movement. Special treaties by which mutual customs concessions were made were only concluded with Italy, Greece, Spain, and Switzerland. Vis-a-vis the other nations Germany had contented herself with obtaining and granting the general concession of the most-favoured- nation clause and entering into an arrangement with Servia and Roumania regarding the duties on certain specified articles. By the nth Article of the Treaty of Frankfurt Germany and France agreed on com- mercial relations to place each other on the same footing as Great Britain, Belgium, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Austria, and Russia. It will thus be seen that, while Germany preserved a free hand in fixing her own customs duties, she enjoyed, in consequence of the most-favoured-nation clause, no PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the full advantages of the European conventional tariffs. " In France, however, where the development of the economic condition of affairs has given rise to great discontent, a strong Protectionist tendency has in the last few years gained the upper hand. It could, therefore, hardly be doubted that the French com- mercial treaty would not extend beyond February ist, 1892. This danger exercised more or less an influence on the other treaty-bound nations of Europe, and their desire to protect their home production became more and more clearly apparent. " The nearer the critical point — the expiration of the existing European treaties — approached, and the more certain it became that the advantages of auto- nomy in its own tariffs, coupled with participation in the treaty concessions of other States, hitherto enjoyed by Germany, would at that time come to an end, the more the necessity of taking a decision in regard to its future action was imposed upon the German Government. Germany had to decide whether she would follow the example of other States in their Protective tariffs and on her side close the market to foreign goods, thereby considerably contributing to increase the Protectionist movement, or whether she should intervene in time to hinder its further develop- ment, and to obtain a decisive influence over the coming reorganisation of the European customs tariffs in the sense of international arrangement. The decision could only be in favour of the latter course." And of the advantages of the new departure the Government said : — " These treaties, in their negotiation and in their end, form an inseparable whole, and in the delibera- tions on the concessions made by Germany and the advantages given in exchange therefor, must be regarded as a unity. In the conclusion of these treaties, the object of the Government has been, THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. iii while reserving to Germany the benefit of the neces- sary protection for national industries, to keep open as far as possible foreign markets for her commerce. The concessions which Germany has had to make are, when regarded as a whole, not inconsiderable. The Federated Governments are, however, completely aware of their commercial and financial importance, and have in the negotiations striven successfully to limit them as much as possible. The concluding of the treaties for a term of twelve years will bring about the stability in the customs duties earnestly desired by the business world, and the Government entertain the conviction that they will not only do away with the former dangerous fluctuations in the commercial relations of the Empire, but also tend to increase the volume of its trade and commerce." Having in an earlier chapter followed in detail the arguments by which Prince Bismarck justified his adoption of a policy of high Protection, it is interesting to compare those advanced by his successor in office in defence of a fundamental departure from that policy. And first, argued Caprivi, Protection, in the form of fixed auto- nomous tariffs (1879, 1885, and 1887), had proved a double-edged weapon, for directly Germany had erected higher barriers her neighbours did the same : — " As soon as other States began to make attempts to obtain the same advantages, the wished-for benefits were rapidly turned into disadvantages. These fixed autonomous tariffs helped to favour home industries at a time when technical skill was undergoing great development, but Germany was restricted to her own markets, which became replete with over-production. Industry, therefore, soon began to suffer for want of 112 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. outlets for its goods. Most States began to acquire the advantages of the most-favoured-nation clause, and France and Germany profited in this respect by the article of the treaty of Frankfurt, until Germany at last began to feel the unfavourable side of the arrangement. The most - favoured - nation clause gradually became a cause of general detriment and injury. France then decided upon a maximum and minimum tariff, by w^hich she still profits. Germany feels limited and restricted in her output on foreign markets. The continual increase of imports is a calamity which, in the circumstances, seriously affects German industries, and not only the masters, but also the workmen. The dilhculty had to be dealt with. It is not a question of Free Trade or Protection. These are dogmas and the battle cry of parties, which do not apply to the situation. It is not a question of equalising, balancing, and reconciling opposing interests. It was necessary by means of customs treaties to extend Germany's markets abroad for her exports. This has always been the main object in view throughout the policy of the last twelve years, although obscured by the dispute between the doctrines of Free Trade and Protection. If Germany had continued to favour the policy of the closing up of States against one another it would soon have come to a general conflict. States can shut themselves up one against another, but they will not satisfy them- selves in this way, and are naturally called upon to offer a fair exchange of their products with mutual concessions." After declaring that it was his principle to concede nothing without obtaining a full equiva- lent, he referred to the agricultural aspect of the treaty question : — " The situation of German agriculture is at pre- sent a most unfavourable one. The corn laws were necessary for its protection, and they are still indis- thp: commercial treaty era. 113 pensable. On the other hand, it is certain that in general they have not had the effect expected from them. It is, nevertheless, certain that their existence prevents an agricultural crisis, of which it would be impossible to overrate the evil consequences. A parallel with English conditions is not possible. There it is a question of agricultural magnates, but in Germany a landed proprietor means someone who, with difficulty, extracts an existence from the soil. The chief reason, however, for the necessity for the maintenance of agriculture is exclusively a question of State. I am convinced that such a cultivation of grain is indispensable to us as will, in case of need, J suffice to feed even our increasing population in time of war, and that the State which cannot exist from its own agricultural produce is on the downward path. There may, it is true, sometimes be a bad harvest, but in order to provide against such a con- tingency, especially in war time, we can take the precaution of allying ourselves with grain-growing States on whom we can count even in time of war. I have heard it said that this is an exaggerated view, and that in case of a war with France and Russia we could obtain corn by sea. I would not like to base the existence of the State on such factors. We cannot know what the maritime Powers would, in case of a European conflagration, term contraband of war. In my past life as a soldier I acquired the un- shakable conviction that in the future war the feeding of the army and the nation would be the deciding factor. This deciding factor is affected if agriculture is injuriously affected. But agriculture is able to bear a reduction of the grain duties and yet to prosper. These duties are a heavy burden for the State, as they entail a rise of prices in the necessities of life. The raising of these duties to five marks (per double cwt.) strained the bow too much. Their J existence thereby became a danger to the State, as they formed a reason for popular agitation. The Government, therefore, decided to reduce them." P.G. I 114 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. Coming, then, to the interests of industry, he said : — " The Government have not neglected the claims of German industries, but have in the new tariff done everything to aid their development. To assure the maintenance and prosperity of the working classes markets must be found. The movement of the work- ing population from east to west, from the country to the town, proves that well-paid work is an equiva- lent for the increased cost of living. Well-paid work will be found if the treaties are accepted. Germany must either export wares or men. With the increas- ing population a corresponding increase of national industry is a necessity. . . . When we hear such things as were said at Erfurt [referring to the Social Democratic Congress], one is involuntarily inclined to regard the people there assembled with a certain amount of dislike. We must not, nevertheless, be blind to the value for Germany of a strong labouring class. We must accustom ourselves to regard the workman less pessimistically, and must not abandon the hope of winning him back to us. Herr Stocker has said in this Assembly that we must not only advance towards the workman, but meet him half way. To do this is the object of these treaties. We still take our stand on the basis of the Imperial Message of 1881, in which it was declared that the reparation of social detriment was not to be effected solely by means of repressive measures, but also by increasing the well-being of the working classes. We consider that in these treaties we have been animated by an equal interest in the well-being of both work- men and employers." Speaking, finally, of the political significance of the treaties, he said : — " With regard to the political side of the treaties, in the case of Belgium and Switzerland we have THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 115 simply been actuated by an earnest desire to live on friendly and neighbourly terms with those countries. It is otherwise, however, with the Triple Alliance. This has been concluded for the preservation of peace, , and without the least aggressive aim. But when we conclude such an alliance of peace, we cannot carry on a commercial war with our allies. It is our inte- rest to strengthen our allies, so that if, in spite of all our efforts, the peace of Europe should be broken, they may be powerful and able to bear the necessary armaments. We must, therefore, desire that a State with whom we stand in friendly relations should not be permanently in an unfavourable position. The Governments of these States have mutually taken pains to lind a means of effecting an exchange of products. We desire that these treaties should make a deep impression on the population. At the time of Frederick the Great Princes decided questions of peace and war. Even under Frederick the Great, it was more the policy of that great man that carried away the people than the feeling that Prussia was in danger. The secession of a province excited at that time no emotion. The people lived under the new Prince as under their former master. This state of things is a matter of the past. Since the end of last century wars have been wars of nations, and nowa- days nations must aid their rulers, not only with the hand, but also with the heart. War must be a con- sequence of national feeling. This is the ruling spirit of these treaties. Formerly treaties of Cabinets were negotiated Prince with Prince. To-day the principles of these treaties must be incorporated with the soul of the nation. This, let me hope, will be the result and the action of the commercial treaties in question."' As a complement to this may fitly be added * Speech of December loth, 1891, reported as above in The Times of the following day. I 2 ii6 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the estimate which Prince Bismarck, then Hving in restless retirement, passed upon the treaties : — " The ex-Chancellor said that more than thirty industries were affected by the reduction of the tariff. If these treaties were properly examined it would be seen that not only Austria and Italy had had con- cessions made to them, but also England, France, and America. . . . And who prepared the treaties ? Privy Councillors and officials who are exclusively consumers, and of whom may be repeated the words of the Bible — ' They sow not, neither do they reap.' Those who do not feel the shoe pinch are the gentle- men who have been entrusted with the preparation of these treaties. The bureaucracy of Germany is a national calamity. I would never have had the courage thus to take a leap in the dark which is to produce results for the next twelve years. The hard- ships of the new treaties will first make themselves apparent after they have been put in force, and then it will be too late to alter them. Everything has till now been prepared in secret. It has been said that under the former regime the same tactics of secrecy were observed, but this is a fiction. In 1878 we began to discuss the tariff question in public ; we observed what the English call ' fair play,' and the French cartes sur table. This time, however, secrecy has been observed throughout, and now the Reichstag is called upon to dispose of the whole matter in a few days."^ During the discussions in the Reichstag the treaties received from the Protectionist parties much more opposition than fell to them when the time came for a definitive vote, while the popular parties of all shades welcomed them enthusiastically ^ A speech at Friedrichsruh, reported in The Times of December 15th, 1891. THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 117 as an instalment of Free Trade. Nevertheless, there was the inevitable conflict of interests, agriculture pitting itself against industry, and vice versa ; varied now and then by recrimination and protest where suspicion arose that raw materials were being favoured at the expense of manufactured goods or manufactured goods at the expense of raw materials. It was not with- out reason that the Government had, in their own words, " declined to consult the various industries concerned, believing that in not obtaining the advice of interested parties they would be less biassed than they might otherwise have been." It is significant of the prevalent state of political feeling and of the tension which tariff warfare had produced that the first of these reciprocity treaties, that with Austria, was approved in the Reichstag on December i8th by a majority of 243 against 48, and that 28 members of the Conservative party voted for it. The treaties with Italy and Belgium were then accepted in the same sitting without opposition. It was the great triumph of Caprivi's Ministerial career, and industrial and commercial Germany was not slow or ungrudging in awarding him the thanks and admiration which his achievement deserved. The Emperor's recog- nition of this successful inauguration of the " new ^ course " took the form of a title, and the soldier statesman became henceforth a Count. The words in which, on December i8th, the Sovereign signi- fied the bestowal of this dignity did not exaggerate ii8 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the merits of one of the most faithful, most conscientious, and most straightforward Ministers who has ever served the Empire : — " That simple, homely Prussian General has in two years succeeded in making himself conversant with, and in mastering, problems of extreme difficulty, with a rare political insight. He has, at the right moment, saved the Fatherland from evil consequences. I believe that the achievement represented by the introduction and conclusion of the treaties of com- merce will prove for posterity one of the most impor- tant historical events, and is literally an act of vital moment. I am convinced that not only our Father- land, but millions of the subjects of other countries, which are united to us in the great Customs League, will sooner or later bless this day." In dealing with Austria-Hungary, Germany reduced her corn duties, that on wheat and rye from 50s. to 35s. per ton, that on oats from 40s, to 28s., that on barley from 22s. 6^. to 20s., on maize from 20s. to i6s., on malt from 40s. to 36s., and on flour from 105s. to 76s. The duties on dead meat were likewise reduced — from ids. to 8s. 6d. and ys. 6d. per cwt. ; those on horses from 20s. to ids. each, on oxen from 30s. to 25s. each, on cattle from 6s. to 5s. each, pigs 6s. to 5s. each ; those on figs, currants and raisins from 12s. to 4s. per cwt. ; those on fresh oranges and lemons from 6s. to 2s. A number of industrial duties were also reduced — for example, those on iron, cotton, linen, glass, leather goods, watches, paper, oil, porcelain, earthenware and stoneware, and roofing slates. Austria, on the other hand, reduced many of THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 119 her duties on articles important for the German export trade. The Swiss treaty conceded to Germany reduc- tions averaging 35 per cent, on 293 out of a total of 476 articles scheduled, though many of them were already covered by the most- favoured-nation clause. Treaties were concluded in the autumn of 1893 ^ with Roumania and Servia, and one was concluded J with the Government of Spain, but it was not ratified by the Spanish Cortes, whose pride had not forgotten the Caroline Islands episode. The consequence was that Germany put the legislative tariff in operation with full duties. Spain did the same, whereupon Germany, not to be outdone, added 50 per cent, to many duties on June 30th, 1895, though these increases were abolished on July 25th, 1896. A most-favoured-nation treaty was not concluded with Portugal, which was not particular about commercial complications, and here the tariff of 1887 continued. ^_/ Matters were not so easily arranged with Russia, for before the treaty with that country had been arranged there was waged a tariff war marked by great tenacity and obstinacy, a war in which neither side conquered, yet in which both were vanquished. Before the negotiations had got far, and during an adjournment of the plenipotentiaries, the Russian Government suddenly introduced a new tariff imposing at once upon German manu- factures imported into Russia duties higher by 120 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. 15, 20, and even 30 per cent, than hitherto. Bedin answered St. Petersburg by putting 50 per cent. > on Russian produce from August 1st, 1893.^ Industry and agriculture were embarrassed in both countries while the contention lasted, which was until the very conclusion of a treaty on March 22nd, 1894. By this treaty Russia secured a number of modifications of the old duties of 1887, and Germany was conceded the full advan- tage of the tariff reductions made in favour of France the year before, including those on iron and steel manufactures, worked cast-iron, wire, chemicals, pianos, paper, bottled wine and cham- pagne, agricultural machinery, and woollen goods woven with carded yarn. In addition to these concessions shared with France, Germany also received reductions on steel, coal, woollen goods, and leather goods. The beneficial effects of this treaty were soon seen. In 1894 the value of the goods imported by Russia from European countries was 92,000,000 roubles more than in 1893, and of this increase 45 per cent, fell to Germany, which for the first time took the posi- tion hitherto held by England as Russia's largest provider. Meantime, a more distant country, which had ^ All such emergencies are now effectively covered by a law of May i8th, 1895, which gives the Government power to impose a higher duty up to 100 per cent, beyond the existing tariff, or, in case of duty-free imports, a duty up to 20 per cent, ad valorem, where countries do not give to Germany the most-favoured-uation treatment. THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 121 entered the path of development with singular success, was causing increasing anxiety both to the German agriculturist and the manufacturer. It was Argentina, which, not satisfied with having become a serious rival in corn and cattle, had erected almost insuperable barriers against indus- trial imports, less for the purpose of protecting native enterprise than of compelling the foreigner to keep her in revenue. The last revision of Argentina's tariff dealt a heavy blow at German cotton goods, cloth, paper, wire nails, starch, spirit, malt, and — most audacious cut of all — beer. On December 7th, 1894, a section of the National Liberal party brought forward a resolu- tion in the Reichstag calling on the Government summarily to denounce the most-favoured-nation treaty with this troublesome country. The pro- posal was discussed on March 13th and 14th, 1895, and was referred to a committee by the votes of the Conservative, Catholic, and Polish parties, and the authors of the resolution. The result of the following inquiry was a recommenda- tion, on May 24th, that the Government should denounce not only the treaty with Argentina but all other treaties which were unfavourable to Germany. The committee also urged that measures should be taken to draw together Con- tinental countries in a Customs Union. To the latter suggestion the Secretary of State for Foreign Affairs gave an unsympathetic reception, telling the committee point-blank that they did ■J 124 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. 5>93i459 dollars in 1896, and 6,493,368 dollars in 1897, her imports in 1898 were 5,584,014 dollars, in 1899, 7,393,456 dollars, in 1900, ^^383, 498 dollars, and in 1901, 7,021,405 dollars. InGermanythere is nodifference of opinion what- ever as to the immense value of the commercial treaties of the Caprivi regime. By general consent the remarkable expansion of industrial production at home and trade abroad is attributed largely to the policy of freer exchange which was introduced between 1892 and 1894. Herr Eugen Richter, voicing the Liberal view of the question, says : — " The commercial treaties have not by far regained for Germany the measure of Free Trade which had been exhibited by the earlier commercial treaties up to the commencement of the Protective era in 1879. Their principal significance lies in the reversal of the customs policy of the latter year which they imply, and in the practical recognition that nations have a reciprocal interest in facilitating commercial dealings, instead of isolating themselves, as by a sort of Chinese wall, by the erection of the highest possible tariff barriers." Testimony to the same effect abounds in the reports of the German Chambers of Commerce, the reports of foreign Consuls, and in the Press both of Germany and other countries. Thus the Berlin Merchants' Association reported in 1896 : — " It must be conceded that the treaties have certainly had those favourable consequences for Germany's export trade which impartial judges predicted would result from them. In fact, the commercial and industrial activity which has been THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 125 so apparent in Germany since 1894 is directly due to these treaties." " In their impotent wrath at the conchision of the commercial treaties," wrote the Berlin correspondent of The Times on February 4th, 1896, " the agrarians have always seized upon isolated complaints in the reports of the German Chambers of Commerce as a proof that not only agriculture but industry also had been injured by the recent economic policy of the Empire. Though it could not be expected, perhaps, that the influence of the commercial treaties would be visible at once in the trade returns, the ofhcial statistics of Germany's foreign commerce during 1895 afford a striking refutation of tlie agrarian contentions and an equally striking justification of the supporters of the treaties. Apart from precious metals, the value of the German export trade in 1895 amounted to ;^ 1 6 5, 500, 000, while in 1894 it only amounted to ;f 148,050,000, thus showing an increase of ^17,450,000. At least two-thirds of this increase is due to the aug- mented exportation of purely industrial products, especially of ironware, and though a small decrease is visible in some departments it is of such a trifling character as to be scarcely worthy of notice. As might be expected, this large development of the export trade is accompanied by a considerable increase in the import returns, due to the greater demand for raw material for industrial purposes. In 1895 the value of the imports amounted to ;^204, 600,000, or ;^39, 100,000 more than the value of the exports during the same period." How the trade of later years has more than borne out this early promise will appear from a comparison. During the six years which preceded the coming into operation of the existing treaties of commerce, Germany's exports had amounted to -{■972,600,000, an average of ^^162, 100,000 per 126 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. annum, but during the following six years they amounted to ;^i, 194,900,000, an average of 3^199,150,000, an increase of ;^37j050,ooo a year, and that in spite of an intervening period of commercial depression. The import trade showed the same movement. While the aggregate im- ports for the six years preceding the treaties were ;^i, 270,500,000, an average of ;^2ii, 700,000 per annum, the imports for the six succeeding years were ^£'1,536,260,000, an average of £256,040,000 per annum, showing a yearly increase of ;^44,340,ooo. Taking individual countries, while in 1890, just before the treaty era opened, Germany sold goods to Austria-Hungary to the value of ^17,550,000, equal to 10-3 per cent, of her entire export trade, she sold her goods in 1900 to the value of ;^25, 536,000, or 10-8 per cent, of the whole; she sold goods to Russia in 1890 to the value of ;^io,3oo,ooo, or 6-i per cent, of the whole, but in 1900 to the value of ;£i7,243,90o, or 6*8 per cent, of the whole; she sold goods in 1890 to Switzer- land to the value of ^£9,000,000, or 5-3 per cent, of the whole, but in 1900 to the value of £14,602,700, or 6-1 per cent.; she sold goods to Belgium in 1890 to the value of £7,540,000, or 4*4 per cent., but in 1900 to the value of £12,655,000, or 5-3 per cent. In each case there has been a considerable increase, both absolutely and relatively, and this increase, in Germany at any rate, is universally placed to the credit of the enlightened policy of Count von Caprivi. Upon this subject. Professor THE COMMERCIAL TREATY ERA. 127 Lujo Brentano wrote while the fate of the new tariff (of 1902) was still uncertain : — " Germany changed Free Trade for a system of Protectionist solidarity {Anglice, ' a self-contained Empire') in 1879, and if German economy has never- theless advanced it is, thanks to science, to the chemical laboratories of our Universities and the technical instruction of our Polytechnics. Even so, Germany's share in the trade of the world remained stationary during the 'eighties and in most years was behind even that of France. To-day it is different. France fell back in the 'nineties into the same system of Protectionist solidarity. In Germany, on the other hand, what progress since we began with the beginning of the 'nineties to approximate Free Trade again ! ... In fact, since the conclusion of the Caprivi com- mercial treaties the wealth of Germany has increased as in no equal period of its long history before ; the population has rapidly grown ; emigration has fallen to a figure unknown in the whole history of the nineteenth century, and other nations, full of astonish- ment, envy us this. Does it not seem as though some evil fate had blinded us, that so many of our people should to-day be crying down these commercial treaties, while others, standing indolently aside, are shortsightedly vying with each other, by strengthening the Protectionist system, in destroying that which has brought us such great prosperity." 128 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER VIII. THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. With the passing of the Caprivi treaties there came into prominence a political movement which has since disputed with Social Democracy both for fame and notoriety. It is the movement known as agrarianism, whose demand is that agriculture shall be regarded by the State as its primary concern, and shall be given preference over every other economic interest. Manufactures may be crippled ; commerce may be destroyed ; the ship- yards may be deserted ; the mines may stand still ; the great export trade which has been built up during the past twenty years may go to ruin ; labour may be depressed ; the loaf of the poor may be diminished ; but the welfare of the land must be maintained at all risks and at all costs. That, in effect, is the contention of the modern agrarians, the successors of the feudalists whom the laws of Stein and Hardenberg dethroned, whose agitation and influence are as much a power as a perplexity in contemporary German politics. Early in the history of the present Reichstag there was a country party which kept a careful eye upon the interests of agriculture, and especially THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. 129 of the large corn producers, and its organ, the Association of Taxation and Economic Reformers, was in the habit of holding periodical congresses before the era of Protection opened, for the dis- cussion of questions of the land and the promotion of legislation favourable to owner and cultivator. It was an exclusively Conser\-ative organisation, though not as yet quite identical with the Con- ser\ative Parliamentary- party, and even then it made no secret of its antagonism to industn,- and " capitalism." And yet these Taxation Reformers originally were not Protectionists at all, but Free Traders. •• Taking our stand on the basis of Free Trade," ran one of the articles in their statutes, " we are opposed to protective duties, though, on the other hand, we regard the question of import duties and excise duties as an open one. With all financial duties and indirect taxes care must always be taken that they do not exert a specially injurious influence on individual districts and classes of the population." It was not long, how- ever, before the Grst part of this article was excised, and the world saw no more of it. Nevertheless, as late as 1S76, though the return to Protection was so near, the official programme of the Con- servative and agrarian fractions made no reference to the re\"ision of the customs tariff. " In oppcsition to the unrestricted freedcn: of Liberalistic theory-.'" said a manifesto o* -"--- year, " we desire for the Life of :ndu5tr\ ? - :? an ordered freedom. We require P.G. iL 128 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER VIII. THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. With the passing of the Caprivi treaties there came into prominence a poHtical movement which has since disputed with Social Democracy both for fame and notoriety. It is the movement known as agrarianism, whose demand is that agriculture shall be regarded by the State as its primary concern, and shall be given preference over every other economic interest. Manufactures may be crippled ; commerce may be destroyed ; the ship- yards may be deserted ; the mines may stand still ; the great export trade which has been built up during the past twenty years may go to ruin ; labour may be depressed ; the loaf of the poor may be diminished ; but the welfare of the land must be maintained at all risks and at all costs. That, in effect, is the contention of the modern agrarians, the successors of the feudalists whom the laws of Stein and Hardenberg dethroned, whose agitation and influence are as much a power as a perplexity in contemporary German politics. Early in the history of the present Reichstag there was a country party which kept a careful eye upon the interests of agriculture, and especially THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. 129 of the large corn producers, and its organ, the Association of Taxation and Economic Reformers, was in the habit of holding periodical congresses before the era of Protection opened, for the dis- cussion of questions of the land and the promotion of legislation favourable to owner and cultivator. It was an exclusively Conservative organisation, though not as yet quite identical with the Con- servative Parliamentary party, and even then it made no secret of its antagonism to industry and " capitalism." And yet these Taxation Reformers originally were not Protectionists at all, but Free Traders. " Taking our stand on the basis of Free Trade," ran one of the articles in their statutes, " we are opposed to protective duties, though, on the other hand, we regard the question of import duties and excise duties as an open one. With all financial duties and indirect taxes care must always be taken that they do not exert a specially injurious influence on individual districts and classes of the population." It was not long, how- ever, before the first part of this article was excised, and the world saw no more of it. Nevertheless, as late as 1876, though the return to Protection was so near, the official programme of the Con- servative and agrarian fractions made no reference to the revision of the customs tariff. " In opposition to the unrestricted freedom of Liberalistic theory," said a manifesto of that year, " we desire for the life of industry and trade aa ordered freedom. We require of economic legislation P.G. K 130 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. that it shall pay equal attention to all productive activities and take just account of the now inade- quately regarded interests of the larger landowners, of industry, and of handicrafts. In this sense we call for the gradual removal of the privileges accorded to the great capitalists. We call for the amelioration of the grave injuries which exaggerated economic centralisation and the lack of systematic regulations for agriculture and the small industry have produced. In particular we call for the revision of the law of maintenance domicile and of the Industrial Code which experience shows to be necessary." To recall a programme so moderate is to indicate the distance which the agrarian movement has travelled in the interval. So long, however, as there remained at the helm a Chancellor so favourably disposed to agriculture as Prince Bismarck, the agrarians were relieved from anxiety and apprehension. Only when there came to office a Minister free from prejudices in favour of the landed class, or of any single class whatsoever, did the agrarians form themselves into a solid party, and determine systematically to pursue a purely personal and interested policy. The first clear departure from the Bismarck tradition took place, as we have seen, when Caprivi decided at the beginning of the 'nineties to modify the existing agricultural duties, as fixed by the revised tariff of 1887, with a view to affording industry fair play and an opportunity of gaining an entrance to markets — Russia and Austria in particular — then closed owing to Germany's em- bargo, on agricultural imports. It was Caprivi's THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. 131 declaration, in a speech in which he commended the treaty policy to the Reichstag, that "Germany is no longer an agricultural but an industrial country," that for the first time opened the eyes of the agrarians to the economic revolution which had passed over the country. So direct a chal- lenge to fight for their position and privileges the agrarians could not well have resisted, and if they failed to prevent the conclusion of the commercial tariffs of 1892 to 1894 it was not from lack of effort. No sooner, however, had the treaties been ratified than they began a vehement agitation against them in agricultural circles, and the rural constituencies suddenly became the scene of un- wonted political activity. " We must tear up the treaties with Austria and Italy," said the frantic Kreuzzeitung, that time-honoured champion of law and order, on November 24th, 1893, and later, when the treaty with Russia came into existence amid Imperial felicitations, the organ of the rural party came perilously near to Vese- majeste, by flatly declaring that "the German farmer will now be inclined to regard the Emperor as his political enemy." From that time the agrarians closed their ranks for the strenuous defence of their threatened privileges, and the course of later domestic politics has to a large extent been determined by their influence and action. The first concrete expression of the more aggressive spirit which gained ascen- dency at the beginning of the 'nineties was the K 2 132 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. formation of the Farmers' League, more commonly known as the Agrarian League,^ the originator of which was a Silesian tenant farmer named Ruprecht. " What I propose," said this spokesman of the smaller cultivators, in a fiery oration which woke up the sluggish spirits of the peasantry of the South, " is no less than this — that we join with the Social Democrats and seriously make common cause against the Government and show them that we are not prepared to tolerate our present bad treatment, and let them feel our power. It is necessary at last to give expression in plain words to the justifiable dis- content which is heard wherever farmers meet together. We must cry so that the whole country hears. We must cry so that our voice reaches the halls of Parliament and of the Ministries. We must cry until our voice is heard on the steps of the throne itself. We must strike out of the statutes of our agricultural associations all the paragraphs that exclude politics, for we must carry on politics, and politics, moreover, in our own interest. Let us have but the courage to take the name 'agrarians' which newspapers antagonistic to agriculture have often unjustifiably given us. For only by carrying on an uncompromising and unequivocal policy of interests can the existence of the present generation of farmers be saved." The new agrarian movement thus set on foot dates from the end of 1892, though it was February of the following year before the League was formally constituted at a national conference held ^ The Build der Landwirthe, literally, League of Farmers, and alternatively spoken of in the English Press as the Landlords' League and the Agrarian League. The last variant is truest to the composition of this combination, in which landowner and cultivator consort indiscriminately. THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. 133 at the Tivoli Assembly Hall in Berlin — ever since the Mecca of a yearly pilgrimage of agrarians from all parts of the Empire. Meantime, the landowners and Junkers of North and East Prussia had taken up the idea, and it was under their patronage that the League was launched, while from that time to this it has proved the advocate and the mouthpiece far more of the interests of the great corn growers than of the small peasants, whose principal occupa- tion is grazing and cattle breeding. The League, as a propagandist organisation, was a signal success from the first. It speedily won a membership of 200,000, and encouraged by abundant funds it has since maintained a large staff of itinerant lecturers whose business it is to organise the agricultural classes, to instruct them in their grievances, and to see that they apply to the Government effective and continuous pressure, so supporting the hands of the party which exists to protect and to promote their special interests in Parliament. The formal programme of the League embraces the following demands : — I. Adequate customs protection for the produce of agriculture and its dependent industries. 2. No reduction of the existing duties, no com- mercial treaties with Russia and other countries which might have the result of a reduction of the German agricultural duties, and a re-adjustment, in the interests of agriculture, of the treaty with the United States. 3. More protection for agricultural and particularly peasant auxiliary 134 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. industries, such as sugar and spirit manufacture, in the matter of taxation. 4. Prohibition of the import of cattle by sanitary measures from countries where disease is suspected. 5. Introduction of bimetallism as a protection against the fall of the price of agricultural produce. 6. Legislation for the formation of Chambers of Agriculture. 7. Revised legislation upon the subject of domicile, free migration, and breach of contract on the part of labourers (this demand, indeed, going so far as to require that agricultural labourers should be prevented from leaving their native districts even when discontented with the conditions of their employment). 8. Revision of the insurance legis- lation for the benefit of the working classes with a view to transferring the contributions from employers to the whole community, g. Severer State control of the Produce Exchanges in order to check the natural arrangement of prices. 10. Revision of the land laws and the laws relating to mortgage and credit in the interest of landowners and agriculture. 11. The amelioration of local taxation for the benefit of the agricultural classes. These, however, are but the main principles of agrarian policy ; in practice agrarianism means preferential treatment for the landed and agricul- tural classes whenever their interests and those of industry and the consuming public appear to con- flict. Germany has hitherto been an agricultural State, and the status quo must be maintained not only for all future time but at all costs, and to that THE AGRARIAN MOVEMENT. 135 end State policy must be unflinchingly directed. Pages would be needed to record the long list of exceptional laws which have actually been passed in sympathy with this standpoint, and the still longer list of schemes and proposals which, owing to their transparent unreasonableness, have failed to be reaHsed in legislation. To the first list belong, above all, the further revision of the customs tariff in 1902, which remains to be considered ; then laws prohibiting the import of live cattle on pretence of veterinary precautions, although when the disease dreaded had disappeared the restrictions remained ; laws aiming similarly at the exclusion of dead meat by means of a costly and absurdly pedantic system of inspection ; laws regulating the manufacture and sale of margarine ; and the Stock Exchange Act, prohibiting dealings in futures in corn and flour, a measure which has injured the landowners more than any other class, since it has, by restricting the flow of money, made dearer its price at home, and so influenced loans and mortgages unfavourably. So, too, in taxation the agrarians have secured special privileges in connexion with the duties payable on home- produced spirit, and until the conclusion of the Sugar Convention those of their number who cultivated the sugar beet had the benefit of a liberal export premium on every ton of sugar sent abroad, the aggregate bounty running to £"1,500,000 annually. Want of power and not want of will prevented the passing of many other class 136 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. measures which were pressed in vain upon a Parliament never disposed to be too punctiHous in weighing agrarian demands. The most daring proposal which has been made by the agrarians, however, is that which bears the name of Count Kanitz, an East Prussian nobleman who typifies the Junker class and its ideals. This proposal is no less than that the State shall pur- chase outright all the corn imported into the countr}' and retail it at prices which should not be below a favourable average of past years, the idea being, of course, that the market price of the corn thus sold out of the public granaries would determine the price of the entire amount of grain produced at home. When this curious project was first commended to an incredulous and unsympathetic Reichstag on April 7th, 1894, Count Kanitz suggested the average prices which had ruled during the period between 1855 and that year, with a view, of course, of taking advan- tage of the period which preceded the stress of foreign competition. These prices were as follows per ton, and for convenience are given the prices at which corn sold in the open market in Germany in 1894 : — Kanitz Market prices Amount of prices. at Stettin. artificial excess. I 5. 577 34,038,124 76-8 2,104.739 4-8 8,160,435 18-4 1902 43,335.652 32,891,506 75 "9 1 2,063,029 4-8 8.379,919 i9'3 Import s in Valu e — In i,ooc ) Marks. Year. Raw Materials Per- Manu- Per- Food- Per- Total. for centage of Total. factiu'ed centage of Total. stuffs and of Total. Industrial Goods. Cattle. Purposes. 1897 4,864,644 2,100,137 43'2 965,855 ig-S 1,614,705 33'2 1898 5,439.676 2,246,481 4i"3 1,015,129 i8-7 1,819,036 33"4 1899 5.783.628 2,607,014 45'i 1.147,578 19-8 1,728,504 29-9 1900 6,042,992 2,803,097 46'4 1,199,645 19-8 1,762,872 29-2 1901 5,710,338 2,458,769 43'i 1,064,231 i8-6 1,898,235 33'2 1902 5,205,776 2-559.636 44-1 1,102,743 19 'o 1,968,621 33 '9 A peculiar product of the Protectionist system in Germany, as in other countries, are the syndi- cates that have been called into existence for the 170 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. purpose of using to the best advantage the opportunities of profitable trading which are offered by preferential laws. To these passing reference must be made. The syndicate regulates both the production and the sale of the allied industrial concerns, which henceforth are required to transact business entirely through its mediation, and to conform to the regulations which are issued in the common interest by its directive officials. The syndicate thus controls at once production, sale, and prices, and, thanks to its power to check competition and under-selling, it is virtually able to rule the home market and to secure to its members remunerative conditions of trading. An important branch of the syndicate's operations is the promotion of exports by means of premiums, which facilitate the capture of foreign markets :and account for much of the " dumping " of which English manufacturers complain. In Germany no disguise is made of the fact that this cheap selling to foreign countries is only made possible by dearer selling at home. Not long ago a syndi- cate in the iron trade admitted having during six months made a profit of ^60,000 on home sales and a loss of £43,000 on foreign sales. Never- theless, it frequently happens that the syndicating of one industry proves injurious to the interests of another similarl}- organised, and especially is this the case where, owing to monopoly, raw material or unfinished goods are made dearer to industries engaged in the final processes of PROTECTION AND TRADE. 171 manufacture. Not only so, but the syndicates are never slow to take advantage of the conjunctures of the market, whatever be the inconvenience and loss inflicted upon dependent industries. Speaking of the coal famine which seriously handicapped the iron trades in i8gg, Dr. Eugen Moritz, in the work already named, says that the coal syndi- cates " abundantly exploited the situation in their special interests in a manner that can little be com- mended," and he adds: "That the cartels, syndi- catesand trustsshould be placed under State control must appear indispensable to everyone who is versed with the circumstances and who desires the healthy development of our German economic life." So far has the syndicating of trades and industries gone that these combinations now number some hun- dreds, covering every branch of enterprise. While there can be no doubt that the consumer pays more for syndicated goods than for goods purchased in free exchange, this form of industrial combination is widely defended in the interest of labour, which is said to be secured more regular employment and higher remuneration than existed formerly ; though, on the other hand, great hard- ship is occasionally caused where, in the interest of economical concentration, old-established con- cerns are arbitrarily discontinued. An investiga- tion instituted by the Imperial Government led to a sort of official benediction upon the syndicate and the cartel, and in two recent speeches the Prussian Minister of Commerce has commended 172 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the further organisation of industry on the same lines as the surest way of meeting the " American terror," though taking care to warn the syndicates that the immoderate use of their monopoly power would lead to public condemnation and possibly to legislative interference. From the consumer's standpoint the syndicates simply mean higher prices without an}' corresponding advantage. Referring to the coal trade, a German writer stated recently : — " It is an undoubted fact that since the existence of the coal syndicate the profits of the collieries have enormously increased — far more than the miners' wages. According to the admissions of the director of the syndicate, made before the Government Commission, the average price obtained during the years 1894. to igoi increased from 7-83 to iroi marks, or 41 per cent., while the average yearly wages of the colliers increased from 961 to 1224 marks, or 28 per cent." The following dividends declared by some of the most important colliery companies represent a fairly satisfactory return upon capital for years of declining trade : — PROTECTION AND TRADE. 173 Granting, however, that the workpeople em- ployed in the syndicated industries have not in general suffered, the fact remains that the higher profits of capital and the higher wages of labour, where obtained, have come out of the pockets of the consumers. The British Consul-General in Frank- furt has summarised the pro and contra of the question in the following words : — " The old adage," he says, " that competition is the life of trade no longer applies. Syndicates practically do away with competition, which led to technical improvements and inventions, and, as syndicates take in tow also weak concerns, natural selection among the works of the same branch ceases. It has not yet been proved that this is counterbalanced by the efforts of the various members of the syndicates to occupy a prominent position in trade. Syndicates, moreover, endeavour to rule the market, and this compels them to deal very summarily with any new competition that may spring up. They also interrupt all connexion between manufacturer and customer, which is one of the causes of their strength ; for, all individual connexion having been severed, the manu- facturer, if he quitted the syndicate, would find him- self compelled to begin all over again. It is agreed that since the formation of syndicates the capital invested in trade is less subject to risks arising from crises ; prices remain more even and steady, for the crumbling away of prices through under-bidding, especially in times of declining trade, is no longer feared, and the expenses of production are reduced. Thus, the labour market profits, employment and wages have become steadier ; if during bad times the home prices are kept up artificially, wholesale dis- missal of workmen need not be resorted to, and the various trades will more easily acquire an old and experienced stock of workmen." 174 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. To return : how far the retention of the home market, by the exclusion of foreign competition, has been an advantage from the standpoint of the national economy is a separate question, the answer to which must be determined by several considerations. It is obvious that, in so far as by artificial aids industries are started or kept alive which could not without those aids be successfully carried on at all, there can be no benefit to the community. For the gain which is apparently shown by such industries is neutralised by at least equal loss. Private individuals may profit, but it is at the expense of the totality, and in the mean- time productive activities are unremuneratively employed which might have been employed to positive economic advantage. Moreover, to the extent that the exclusion of the foreigner from the home market has the effect of increasing prices, a further direct sacrifice is imposed upon the com- munity, and this again must be placed against any legitimate claim of extended trade. From this standpoint the so-called "protection of national industry " is at best a one-sided measure, for what the producer gains the consumer loses, and even when labour is more hio:hlv remunerated the working man merely receives with one hand in order to pay back with the other. Further, the injury thus inflicted upon the community as a whole is accentuated where, as is so largely the case in Germany, foreign trade is systematically stimu- lated by the low prices which are made possible PROTECTION AND TRADE. 175 owing to the monopoly possessed in the home market, the effect of which is that the home pur- chaser is overcharged in order that the foreigner may be undercharged. The iron industry with its allies is the chief illustration of this system of uneconomic trading, popularly known in this country by the vague term " dumping." The pro- duction of pig-iron in Germany has increased from 4,658,451 tons in i8go to 8,520,540 tons in 1901, 8,402,660 tons in 1902, and 10,085,634 tons in 1903. Naturally this great production of iron of late years has been a forced production, and it was necessary to dispose of a large part of it by forced sales abroad. The exports of the entire iron industry in 1903 were 3,309,000 tons, with a value of £"30,168,750, or £(^ gs. ^d. per ton, against 2,347,211 tons with a value of £"25,862,950 or £"11 OS. 5^. per ton in 1902, and 1,548,557 tons with a value of £"23,980,450 or £"15 los. per ton in igoi, showing a striking decline in prices. Taking pig-iron exports alone, the value per ton was in 1902 £"2 9s. 6d., against £"2 15s. in 1901 and £"4 in 1900. A general fall in values accounts for part of this disparity, but the "dumping" system accounts for still more. The Prussian Minister of Finance, Baron von Rheinbaben, said in the Prussian Diet on January 19th, 1904, " The extraordinarily large export of iron goods has unquestionably helped our iron industry over difficult times. Without this export the works would not have been able to keep going, and 176 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. workpeople would unavoidably have been dis- charged." That is true, and the words suffici- ently explain the policy which the iron industry has pursued — the policy of producing to the full extent of its capacity, selling to the home market as dearly as protective laws and trade combinations will permit, and then disposing of the balance of its production abroad at " cut prices"' (Schlenderpreise) which either afford a very slight margin of profit or no margin at all. Such a system of trading violates sound eco- nomic principles, and the fact that individual manufacturers benefit by it is no answer to the objection that it expressly contradicts the "national" argument by which Protection is most commonly justified. A perfectly impartial Consul of the United States reported to his Govern- ment from Hamburg a few years ago : " Frugality and industry can hardly be expected to accomplish any miracle greater than that of enabling a thrifty workman to keep out of debt. The policy of the countries of Central Europe seems to be to extend and inflate their manufacturing industries indefinitely and suicidally. Their ideal of national prosperity and of happiness seems to be nothing more than the attainment of the ability to export manufactures and import food, and in support of this policy the Governments take from the working-man an import duty on his food in order to give the manufacturer an export bounty." The only compensation which falls to the con- sumer lies in the fact that the export of material sold under cost enables the foreign manufacturer PROTECTION AND TRADE. 177 to re-export finished goods on favourable condi- tions. Hence complaints like that of the Siegen Chamber of Commerce (1903) : — " We cannot pass over in silence the loud com- plaints of many manufacturers of finished goods that cheap German exports of material make it possible' for firms abroad to offer serious competition here." The Cologne Gazette, in giving illustrations of this recently, wrote: — " In transactions with foreign countries there is much underbidding in the German fine-plate trade, so much so that German fine-plate rolling works are unable to compete, in spite of the export premiums which they enjoy, and their trade abroad has been greatly reduced. To all appearance the reason for this is that German half-manufactured material has been sold abroad at such extraordinarily low prices that foreign plate rolling works are able with the help of cheap German material to underbid German competitors on their own ground." It is fair, however, to remember that many persons, while opposed to Protection on economic grounds, defend it on political and social grounds. The prospect of Germany's definite transforma- tion from an agricultural into an industrial State is one which is contemplated by thoughtful people of every political party with regret and misgiving. It is not merely that such a transition must inevitably be accompanied by hardship to the existences which go under, but that the final triumph of industry means the triumph of the factory system and all the hundred-and-one evils which inevitably follow in its train — the decay of P.G. N 178 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. rural life, the densely populated town, the un- healthy life, the physical and moral deterioration which modern industrial conditions occasion and foster. Even avowed Free Trade economists like Professor Walther Lotz frankly recognise the importance of this aspect of the question, and admit the desirability of checking in every natural way the concentration of population in large towns. Nevertheless, the outlook is not by any means so gloomy as pessimistic imaginations are apt to picture it. According to the census of occupations of 1895 the industrial population of Germany was still found to be resident for the most part in towns of medium and of small size, and only to the extent of one-fifth in towns of over 100,000 inhabitants. For example, of every 1,000 persons employed in industry and mining 194*1 were found in towns of 100,000 and up- wards, 146 in towns with from 20,000 to 100,000 inhabitants, 196*8 in towns with between 5,000 and 20,000 inhabitants, 152*4 in towns of between 2,000 and 5,000 inhabitants, and 310*7 in com- munes with less than 2,000 inhabitants. At that time 7,188,758 persons were found to be directly engaged in industry, and their dependents num- bered 8,257,721, making a total industrial popu- lation of 15,446,479. On the other hand, the agricultural labourers numbered 5,500,000, with 3,000,000 dependents. Happily also, deterioration has not yet made the inroad upon the national strength and vitality PROTECTION AND TRADE. 179 which is sometimes alleged, and of degeneracy there can be no talk. The report upon the physical condition of the youth levied for military service during 1902 shows that the urban deca- dence so generally affirmed has little basis in fact. Of every 100 persons born on the land liable to service, 58*64 were found to be efficient when taken from agriculture and forestry, and 58*40 when taken from other employments : a difference of only 0*24 per cent. Of town-born men liable to serve, 58*52 per cent, of those employed on the land were found to be efficient, and 53*52 per cent. of those who followed other employments, a difference in favour of the countryman of only 5 per cent. And yet, however reasonable this fear of industry may be, and however legitimate the plea that the agricultural population, as the healthiest element in the nation, should be protected against decay, even at great sacrifice if need be, it is essential that the State in discharging an obligation of this kind should at least take care that the benefit of the protection given is universally and equally shared and does not become the monopoly of any one class. This, however, it has entirely failed to do. As we shall see, the inevitable result of high agrarian tariffs is to enrich the large land- owners and the large cultivators ; to the small peasantry in general and to the agricultural labourer Protection brings little or no gain, and often positive loss. N 2 i8o PROTECTION IN GERMANY. The attempt has been made to draw conclu- sions favourable to Protection from the returns of emigration. It was, of course, one of Prince Bismarck's favourite theories that emigration was the true index of the country's prosperity, yet even if we accepted this theory as valid for Germany, it would be difficult to base upon it any justifica- tion of the policy introduced in 1879. during the industrial expansion of 1872 no fewer than 125,650 persons emigrated from German ports, and in 1873, when times were still perilously prosperous, 103,638. Then the number fell to 45,112 in 1874, to 30,773 in 1875, to 28,368 in 1876, and to 21,964 in 1877. Industrial and commercial stagnation had now well set in, yet even in 1878, when the last successful blow on behalf of Protection was struck, the number of emigrants was only 24,217, while in 1879 it was 33,227. The following year the new tariff came into full operation, and the emigration rose to 106,190, and in the next year it was 210,574. Taking quinquennial periods, the number of emigrants during the five years follow- ing the French war (1871-1875) was 381,085, and during the five years which covered the transition to Protection (1876-1880) 214,068; but during the following five years (1881-1885) it was 817,763.^ During late years there has been a great decline in this withdrawal of population. In 1887 it was still 99,712, in 1888 it was 98,515, in 1889 it was 90,259, in 1890 it was 91,925, in 1891 it was ^ Karl Strauss in Petermanns Mittheilungen, 1886. PROTECTION AND TRADE. i8i 115,392, and in 1892 112,208. The following years saw the operation of the Caprivi treaties, and the emigration fell to 84,458 in 1893, to 39,178 in 1894, to 35.557 in 1895, to 32,114 in 1896, to 23,220 in 1897, and to 20,837 ^^ 1898, in which year the harvest was specially good. Since then the number has risen to 32,000 (T902). It should be added that since 1897 emigration has been to some extent regulated by a law requiring emigration agents to be registered, and restricting their operations to such ports and even countries of destination as the Imperial Chancellor may from time to time determine. No wise man will too daringly form definite conclusions either way upon figures like the above without taking into consideration other factors which have nothing whatever to do with fiscal policy. A fair verdict upon Protection from the purely economic standpoint would be that while it has undoubtedly preserved the home market for the ^ home producers to a far larger extent than for- merly, it has done this at the cost of the con- sumers. The manufacturing classes have greatly benefited ; but their gain has been the loss of the rest of society. But an economy which does not promote the interests of society as a whole cannot by any right use of the term be called a national economy ; it is a class economy pure and simple. And this is what the policy of Protection has gradually become in Germany. Commended originally by its author on the score of its i82 PROT?:CTION IN GERMANY. reasonableness and moderation, and by him lauded as superior to the earlier policies of prohibition and exclusion, because it sought to combine pro- tection for industry and agriculture with a scru- pulous regard for the interests of the consumers, it has step by step grown into a huge political system for guaranteeing the two great branches of production security for their capital and a remu- nerative return for their investments. The late Dr. Schaffle pointedly characterised the demands of the modern Protectionist in Germany in the following words, and though they were meant to refer particularly to the agrarian they apply to the industrialist as well : — " The Protectionists of our time no longer ask, as did the Protectionists of earlier times, for protection for the purpose of cultivating new or young branches of production or against crises, but without disguise demand a State guarantee, by means of customs duties, of a definite interest on capital and rent of land. Not temporary support of agriculture in its endeavour to accommodate itself to the universal obligation to pass over to a more intensive system of farming, and to the new international competition, but the maintenance of the rent of the land which was attained up to 1875 is the real gist of the matter. It is as if the investor asked for protection so that the rate of interest might not fall, or the capital sunk in industry and trade required protection so that old undertakings might be continued without loss." The word is like poison on the tongue of the average Protectionist, whether agrarian or in- dustrialist, yet in effect his demand implicitly concedes the Communistic principle. For if the PROTECTION AND TRADE. 183 landowner is to be secured his rent, and the capitahst his interest, why not the merchant his profits, the workman his wages, the professional man his fees, and everybody else his special form of remuneration ? But a system of universal bounties, under which everybody is equally sub- sidised at the common expense — which means in the last resort his own — would be nothing less than Communism sans phrase. That was why Count von Caprivi with statesman-like foresight ranked agrarianism with Social Democracy as one of the revolutionary elements in society. It remains to be added that while the advocates of industrial duties continue powerful enough to influence legislation, the manufacturing and mer- chant classes are no more Protectionist in a body than are the same classes in England. Not only so, but many of the most sagacious spokesmen of industry contend that a return to Free Trade would in time equip Germany far more efficiently than in the past to compete for trade on a large and imposing scale in the markets of the world. Referring to the progress which has already been made in this direction, Dr. Eugen Moritz writes : — "The reasons for this striking development are first of all to be sought in the economic consolidation of the German Empire and its concentration upon remunera- tive industry and foreign trade. The inventions in regard to the application of steam and electricity, the discoveries in chemistry, the revolution in machine and railway construction, formed the starting point i84 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. for the creation of industry on a large scale, which industr}', fostered by Germany's peace policy, has grown to its present prosperity."^ And speaking of the iron industry in particular, he contends that its expansion would have taken place without any protective duties at all, while his final conclusion is that the future success of Germany's industry and export will best be furthered by the gradual adoption of a Free Trade policy. Views like these have never been isolated, but they are more common to-day than ever before. So long as agrarianism was moderate in its demands it was possible for the industrialists to work with it to mutual advantage. Now, however, that the agrarians insist more and more on regarding Protection solely from their own standpoint, and indeed demand severer tariffs for the express pur- pose of stemming the progress of industry, it is not difficult to foresee the time when the breach of the old compact might become a vital necessity for the manufacturing interest, and with that breach a new era of freer international trade would at once begin. ' " Eisenindustrie, Zolltariff, und Aussenhandel," Berlin, 1903. CONDITION OF THE WORKING MAN. 185 X CHAPTER XI. THE CONDITION OF THE WORKING MAN. In commending Protection to his countrymen in 1879 Prince Bismarck laid special stress upon the need for the "protection of national labour." Let the foreigner only be prevented from com- peting on free and equal terms in the home market, and as a result of the stimulus which would be given to industry the working man would be assured far more favourable conditions both of labour and of life. A pertinent comment upon this plea, which still continues to occupy a leading place in the case for Protection, was passed by a labour deput}^ in the Reichstag this year. " The working man," he said, " receives no benefit from the duties, and the middle (consuming) class is seriously injured by them. If it were true that Free Trade reduces wages, then wages should be lowest in England and highest in Russia, but the fact is exactly the reverse. Wages in England are far higher than in Germany ; in Russia they are miserable." Whether they are right or wrong, the conclusions here expressed are enter- tained by the entire labouring population, whose [86 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. uncompromising hostility to Protection is rooted in a profound conviction ofitsharmfulness and harsh- ness as well as of its inequality. How far this conviction is justifiable may be more fairly judged when the facts of labour's condition in Germany- are before us. There is no denying that wages have increased during recent years, yet the increase has in general taken place on rates which have been unknown in England for half a century. Even so, the wages paid in the two countries to-day yield some startling contrasts. Thus, returns published by the Metal Workers' Union show that of 8,951 journeymen locksmiths employed in Berlin in I903> 5>040 earned 3s. 6d. a day and upwards, 3,163 earned between 2s. 8^d. and 3s. 5*^., and 758 earned between 2s. 2^d. and 2s. yd. a day. An agreement concluded between the master locksmiths and their employees guaranteed to men out of their time a minimum of 4^. an hour from 1904 forward. In England the average rate is 4s. 6d. a day. According to official returns the average yearly wages paid in the collieries of Prussia in 1901 and 1902 were — District. Upper Silesia Lower Silesia Dortmund ... Saarbriicken Aix-la-Chapelle I90I. 1902. £ s- d. £ s. d. 43 12 .. 41 43 II ■• 39 19 ... 61 4 .. 56 II ... ■ ... 52 2 •• 52 13 58 2 •• 55 19 CONDITION OF THE WORKING MAN. 187 The wages in the iron ore mines were : — District. 190 r, 1902. i ^. d. £ s. d. Mansfeld > ■ • 50 I ., - 43 5 Upper Harz 33 18 ., • 34 3 Siegen-Nassau . . . 45 4 ., ,. 39 6 Other districts right of the Rhine • • • 40 13 ., ■• 39 3 Other districts left of the Rhine ... ^6 2 . .. ^4 It is often interesting to see ourselves as others see us, and this is a picture of British labour drawn by two German State mining officials who had been sent here to spy out the land : — " Wages iu the mining industry of Great ikitain are, as a whole, higher than in Prussia ; the working hours, however, in the four or five regular working days per week are longer in England than in Prussia. . . . The English miner, apart from Northumberland and Durham, works longer day shifts, Saturdays excepted, than the German miner. Throughout the whole year, however, he works fewer shifts than the German miner, and he employs more frequently than the latter a whole day or half a day for recreation, amusement, and attendance at meetings. His higher wages allow him to incur the necessary expenses. The English miner employs his higher wages in better eating and drinking, that is to say, in procuring better and more nourishing food. Hence the greater working capacity of the Englishman." It is a German coal miner also who speaks in a revealing little book written not long ago with the title " How the English Workman Lives," ^ and the following is his impression of German and English conditions of labour : — ' By Ernst Diickershoff (published in translation by P. S. King & Son). i88 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. " In my opinion, the workman makes and maintains a home more easily in England than in Germany. It might be thought that a German workman ought to be able, with diligence, to save a little. But, on the other hand, where living is cheap, wages are low. If the workman goes nearer the town, where wages are higher, he fmds rent and provisions are higher, too ; and if he wants to rent a piece of ground, the owner cannot put too high a price upon it. I have tried in every way to effect some saving, but to no purpose. My monthly average in Germany was eighty marks {£^ 8s. ^d.). Here I received during 1895, according to the colliery books, ;^77 iis. yd. It must be admitted, however, that I was favoured, because I had to fetch my wife and four children out of Germany. I know well that I can make some- thing out of two years' work here, for saving is easy to a German where it is hard to an Englishman, because the latter makes more demand upon life. The chief advantage of all is the cheapness of flour. If everything else is wanting, at least one can always get bread. I have talked over the subject with many Germans round about, and have often received the answer, ' Germany is all very well if one has English money to spend in it.' " Again, the average 37earl3'' wages of the musical instrument makers — representing in Germany a very important industry — were in 1888 -^35 15s. ; in 1899 they had risen to £36 gs. ; in 1900 they were £33 i8s. ; and in 1901 £^6 8s. ; an increase of 13s. a year in eleven years. So, too, the wages of masons run from 5^. to yd. per hour, and it is not without significance that the majority of the strikes which take place in Germany fall to the building trades. Thus in 1903 the masons of Konigsberg struck work to CONDITION OF THE WORKING MAN. 189 secure an advance of wages from the ruling rates of from ^^d. to ^f^d. an hour. After thirteen weeks' idleness they were successful in securing an immediate advance to 5f^., with a promise of ^d. more in 1904, but the victory lost the funds of their trade union some hundreds of pounds. A calculation made by the trade unions of the Saxon textile industry in 1903 showed that the average wages of employees in that industry, in- cluding overseers, only amounted to £^2 15s. per year. A contributor^ to Schmoller's Jahrbuch in 1903 gave the following comparison of standard wages in Germany and England, based on inquiry in both countries ; I have added, where possible, the corresponding figures published in the Board of Trade's fiscal Blue Book : — /^„ United Board of Trade Oermany. Kingd om Bl ue Bool • £ s. d. £ s. d. £ *v. I I 15 / I 14 7 I 15 The approximation between the higher Berlin price and the amount of the duty is too close to be merely accidental. It will be seen that while between the years 1879 and 1899 the price of wheat fell in Berlin £2 los. per ton, it fell in London £^. AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 213 Again, the price of wheat in England in the wholesale market during the years 1890 to 1900 ranged from £"5 js. to 5^8 13s. per ton, falling in the latter year to £6 ys., while in Prussia the price ranged from £6 15s. to ;^ii 2s., falling to £j 15s. ; in Bavaria from £y 25. to £11 15s., falling to £8 3s. ; in Baden from 5^7 9s. to ;fii us., falling to ;^8 iis. ; and in Saxony from £6 12s. to ;^ii 3s., falling to £8 6s. in 1899. Comparing the figures for the later year, we get the result — England, £6 ys. ; Prussia, £y 15s. ; Bavaria, £835.; Baden, £8 lis.; Saxony, £8 6s.; giving an average for the German States of ;^8 ^s. gd., or £1 16s. gd. more than the English price, the German duty being £1 15s. Long before the tariff had by repeated revisions been brought to its present height the agrarian party declared in a formal manifesto to the nation : — "Agriculture does not wish to enrich itself at the cost of others ; it only wishes to see the average prices of the last fifteen years fairly maintained, since lower prices would mean its destruction. . . . Expert authorities on German agriculture declare it to be beyond doubt that Germany can itself produce the present excess of corn imports if only it be fostered more than hitherto, more after the example of Frederick the Great." At the time these words were written the duties on food-corn were fixed at los. per ton : they now vary from £2 10s. to £2 15s., and if the agrarian party had had their way they would have been £^ 15s. all round. 214 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. It is more difficult to follow the effect of the duties upon live stock, the imports of which depend upon many factors independent of pro- tective measures. Where there has been a falling off here it has probably been due less to duties than to sanitary restrictions. Yet the effect upon prices, and hence upon the cost of meat, has been none the less perceptible, while writers qualified to speak from the breeder's standpoint are by no means unanimous in regarding the exclusion of foreign live stock as either judicious or economical. The Hungarian writer Matlekovits^ says : — " Whether it is good for the national economy of Germany that the cheaper cattle of Austria-Hungary should not only be excluded from the food market, but should be rejected for labour and breeding pur- poses, and that in this way the cost of meat should be artificially increased, and the German working classes should be prevented from consuming a larger amount of flesh food, and the German farmer be prevented from buying strong young cattle for draught, breeding, and feeding purposes from neighbouring countries, it should no longer be necessary to discuss in a country whose famous writers, Roscher at the head, have described the development of cattle breeding in so masterly a manner. Agrarianism has many errors to its account, but that it should have inflicted injury upon itself by prohibiting the import of cattle out of countries of less intensive agriculture, and for the same purpose should have had resort to sanitary restrictions, is one of the greatest of all, and belongs to those mistakes that can inflict the greatest disasters upon a country's entire economy." > "DieZoUpolitikderOesterreich-ungarischen Monarchic seit ib68" (1891). AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 215 Time will alone show how wise the agrarians have been in insisting upon measure after measure of restriction and exclusion until the live stock of the country is to-day less relatively to population : than it was thirty years ago. The following was the ratio to every hundred of the population in different years : — 1873. 1883. 1893. 1897- 1900. Cattle... 38-4 . •• 34'5 • •. 34-5 • •• 35"4 •• •• 337 Sheep... 6o"6 ,. ,. 42-2 ., .. 27-8 ., .. 27-8 ., ,. 17-2 Pigs ... 17-4 .. ,. 20'I ., .. 20-I ., .. 27-3 ., ,. 29-6 The extent to which the price of meat has in- creased and the effect of that increase upon the diet of the working classes have already been considered. Furthermore, it is a mistake to suppose that the corn duties favour agriculture equally or even generally. In the opinion of many, far from benefiting the small peasantry the system of Pro- tection has exposed them in a still greater degree than before to the competition of the larger landed proprietors. The leaders of the agrarian move- ment profess to advocate the cause of agriculture as a whole, and endeavour to convince the small farmers that their interests are in every respect identical with those of the great landowner. That pretence was long ago exploded, and is indeed inconsistent with the attitude of a large part of the so-called Kleinbauern (small peasantry) who neither sought further Protection nor desired it, believing that it could only tend to their 2i6 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. impoverishment. Higher corn duties, in fact, are only beneficial to the great producers — to the owners of large estates supporting little popula- tion. The peasantry of the smaller communes produce corn in the main for consumption, and but little, if at all, for sale, and are often, indeed, unable to supply the whole of their needs in grain, so that they have to purchase the deficiency in the market. Most of these small farmers largely continue to follow the old plan of having their corn threshed for them in the neighbouring mills. To the extent that they use their own grain, it is a matter of little importance to them whether the duties are high or low. Directly, however, they become buyers they begin to feel the pinch like the urban consumer, and they are shrewd enough to recognise that for their wealthy neighbours the game of Protection is one of " Heads we win, tails you lose." Not only so, but under the tariff these small farmers have to pay more heavily for their implements and imported manures. How large is this class of cultivators may be judged from the occupation census of 1895. In that year the number of persons following agriculture for their subsistence was 17,815,187, of whom inde- pendent farmers with the members of their families numbered 11,300,108 (about 2,000,000 being de- pendents — children or other relatives employed for wages), while the remaining 6,500,000 were in the main labourers. In round numbers 25,000 large owners divide one-quarter of the land between AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 217 them ; then come 281,000 large peasant pro- prietors, owning together one-third; making 306,000 persons to 54 per cent, of the soil. Here the corn-grower's interest in protective duties is obvious enough. But then follow in order of territorial importance no fewer than 5,250,000 smaller cultivators — proprietors and leasehold tenants — of whom about 1,000,000 hold between 5 to 20 hectares (7I to 50 acres), 1,016,238 from 2 to 5 hectares (5 to yi acres), representing an aggregate area of 4,142,000 hectares ; and 3,236,000 with 2 hectares and under, with an aggregate area of 2,416,000 hectares. Two successive Chancellors of the Empire, Count von Caprivi and Prince Hohenlohe, agreed in accepting the estimate that only corn-growing farms of at least five hectares have any interest at all in the increase of the price of corn, which means that only from one-fourth to three-tenths of the entire agricultural industry is affected one way or the other. The larger estates, exceeding five hectares, comprise an area of 36,727,000 hectares, the small ones an area of 6,558,000 hectares. Prince Hohenlohe stated the matter pointedly in a speech of March 29th, 1895, in which he said : — " Holdings under 12 hectares have no corn to sell, but on the contrary are for the most part themselves buyers. Holdings of 6 hectares and below, even with good soil, are at best able to cover the corn needs of the owners and their families. The number up to 12 hectares comprise four million holdings, or 76 percent, of all the agricultural holdings. Reckoning 2i8 PROTECTION IN GERMANY, 3^ persons per holding, they represent a population of hfteen millions, who with relatively few excep- tions suffer direct loss owing to the increase of the price of food. . , . Thus there remains a population of four millions for whom the Kanitz proposal [of fixed corn prices guaranteed by the State] offers advantage." At the highest computation, a million members of the agrarian class, or less than a quarter of the whole, monopolise the entire advantage of the duties, and do this to the direct prejudice of the majority of their fellow agriculturists and to the injury of the entire consuming community. As to population, this privileged class represents at the outside between four and five million persons — the estimate of Prince Hohenlohe, as we have seen, was only four millions — out of a total popu- lation of fifty-six millions. The agrarians can, however, be cited in evidence against their own contention that Protection is a universal interest of agriculture. Not long ago the German Agricul- tural Council, with the object of supporting the demand for higher duties, instituted inquiries relative to 1,524 holdings, and received the un- expected information that only 26*4 per cent, of the receipts from these farms, which had an aggre- gate area of 518,000 acres, came from corn; 40*6 per cent, came from cattle, butter, and cheese, and i6'3 per cent, from rape seed, sugar, beet, and potatoes. The proportion which fell to corn in so pastoral a State as Bavaria was as low as I5"5 per cent. It is significant also that Dr. Rubow, who recently investigated the agricultural economy of AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 219 the rural commune of Schwessin, in Pomerania, with a view to discovering the practical value of the corn duties, found that only one farmer regu- larly produced corn for sale, and even he could only spare from two or three tons of rye a year, though he had twenty-four hectares (60 acres) of arable land. Only in time of financial need did any other of the peasants sell either rye or oats, and then only a few hundredweights. Taking the whole of the 205 farmers, he found that they did not sell ten tons of grain a year, and that the total revenue from this source was only ;£'6o, or 6s. a head. Not only so, but every single peasant was compelled to buy grain of some sort in order to supplement his own produce. Hence the corn duties were a positive injury to this rural commune, and there are hundreds like it. Dr. Rubow found that the aggregate produce of the commune amounted to 713 tons; while, on the other hand, the consump- tion of corn for bread, for stock-feeding purposes, and for seed was 925 tons, leaving 212 tons to be purchased. The duties upon this purchased corn represented a loss to the commune of £^34 10s., and the new duties will increase this loss to £476, or as much as would liquidate the whole of the communal taxation. Facts like these — and it is the small peasant's tardy recognition of them which accounts for the decadence of the agrarian movement in some dis- tricts which were formerly strongholds of the famous League — emphasise not only the unfairness 220 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of the corn duties, even from the cultivator's stand- point, but the hollowness of the cry of " Agricul- ture in danger ! " which imposed upon the too ready credulity of Count von Biilow, who throughout the recent tariff controversy acted rather as the advocate of the great proprietors than as the spokesman of the common interest. It is not German agriculture, but the system of large, ill- managed estates which has been handed down from feudal times, that is imperilled, and to the latter every successive increase of the corn duties, though it may afford relief for the moment, is in truth both a warning and a menace. The healthiest part, perhaps the only healthy part, of the agricultural industry in Germany to-day is the so-called Kleinbetrieb — that system of petite culture of the value of which John Stuart Mill was so sensible, and which accounts so largely for the comparative wealth of rural France. " In all German States [wrote a German economist recently] the larger the system of agriculture the more it is threatened by forced sales. The large system of farming cannot compete with the small, because corn-growing is not as remunerative as the breeding of cattle and the production of meat. . . . To-day the peasant, in spite of his less intelligence, is economically superior to the large proprietor. Hence in the East of Germany every division of a large estate must be regarded as a sign of economic progress." Slowly but surely this lesson is being learned. Official returns show that during the years 1882 to 1895 there was an increase of 26,318 in the number AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 221 of farms in Prussia between I2| and 25 acres, an increase of 17,152 in farms between 25 and 50 acres, and one of 1,445 in farms between 50 and 250 acres. On the other hand, there was a de- crease of 852 holdings between 250 and 2,500 acres. Commenting upon these figures, an official statistician remarks : "The farmer's calling has not lost in attraction, but on the contrary has greatly gained. The con- tinual laments about the decay of agriculture have not prevented a large section of the population from turning to this occupation, a very strilcing fact the explanation of which is most likely to be found in the great development of cattle breeding." It is significant also that comprehensive statistics prepared by the Government of Brunswick, and extending to the year 1897, show that the small peasantry are as a whole much less encumbered with debt than the large landowners. Incidentally it may be noted that where a decline of population has taken place in rural Germany it has generally been in the districts in which large estates predominate, and that in districts where small proprietorships are in the ascendant population has increased. Thus there has been a larger decrease of population in the Prus- sian provinces of Pomerania, Posen, East and West Prussia, Brandenburg, and Silesia, than in other parts of the monarchy, and there it will be found that estates of 100 hectares and over form between 42 and 65 per cent, of the area devoted to agricul- ture. On the other hand, it is noticeable that 222 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. Saxony, a country free from the disadvantages under which the North and East of Prussia labour, reports not only a largely increased area of land under corn, but increased productivity, both in yield and in value. Between 1891 and 1897 its yield of wheat, rye, barley and oats was 772,690 tons ; in 1898 it was 856,644 tons, an increase of 83.954 tons. The value of the corn of all kinds grown in Saxony in 1898, according to Leipzig Produce Exchange prices, was ^^6,612, 869, against an average for 1891-1897 of ^^5,721,309, an in- crease again of ;^89i,56o. Finally, there was a larger value per hectare of land cultivated of ■£1 16s., viz., £1^ I2S. in 1898 against £11 i6s. for the preceding seven years. To recapitulate, that agriculture carried on under the combined disadvantages of unscientific methods, want of capital, an oppressed labouring class, and incompatibility with the changed needs of the times, could prosper is a flat impossibility, and it is only by the fallacious policy of increasing the protective duties from time to time, as the pressure of circumstances has increased, that the corn-growers of the North have been enabled so far to stave off the necessity of looking the hard facts of their position fairly in the face. There are, no doubt, many districts which, owing to the dryness of the soil and to climate, are unsuited to grazing, and are necessarily restricted to arable farming, but when all proper deductions have been made on that account, the fact remains that AGRICULTURE UNDER PROTECTION. 223 unwillingness to change their ancient ways is a great cause of agricultural stagnation and decline in most parts of the country. And agriculture, as the great landowners understand it, will con- tinue to be " in danger " so long as they refuse to take a lesson from the book of the small cultivators, who in Germany, as in Denmark and Holland, have held their own in spite of every disadvantage of restricted capital and lack of mechanical appliances of the most improved kind. 224 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. CHAPTER XIII. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. •* Protection," wrote once Professor Adolf Wagner, one of the few Protectionists of the Chair in Germany, " will secure the home grain market, and so increase the income of the entire agricultural population." We have seen that it has failed entirely to secure the home market for the home grower, for the latter has either been unable or unwilling to claim that which was reserved for his exclusive use. The agricultural labourer has also waited in vain for the promised benefits. His condition in Germany is well worth studying. Happily there is to-day nothing in England that can be compared with the system of semi-feudalism which still prevails in North Germany east of the Elbe, a system under which progressive agriculture is almost unknown, and the labouring class is kept in a condition hardly to be distinguished from the serfage of a hundred years ago. In the discussion of the question of Free Trade and Protection it is too often assumed that the industrial labourer is the centre of the problem, and the labourer on the land is ignored. Yet unless the imposition of corn duties, with a consequent higher price of produce, higher rents, THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 225 and a higher value of land, not merely ameliorates the condition of the agricultural labourer but entirely raises his status in society and civilisation, Protec- tion passes condemnation upon itself. Now it has been proved over and over again that, despite the decline of corn prices which took place during the second half of last century, rents on the whole increased to an enormous degree. While, however, the price of grain has fallen and the wages of labour have shown an upward tendency, many other articles of consumption and use, as well as rents and taxation, have advanced, so that the labourer's actual position is in general but little better. Not only so, but such progress as the agricultural labourer has made has been due less to the desire, or even the willingness, of the land- owners to improve his position than to the com- petition for his services which was set up by the manufacturers in the 'seventies and onward. In the middle of the nineteenth century wages in North Germany rarely exceeded gd. a day, and it was several years after the French war before they advanced to is. In the words of a recent German writer : — "Agricultural wages have only increased in a time of sinking corn prices, when the development of industry led to such an increase of the workpeople therein engaged that the agricultural employers, in order to obtain labourers at all, were compelled to pay higher wages as well." The best that Professor von der Goltz, one of the highest German authorities upon the land P.G. Q 226 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. question, can say of the position of the rural labourers is that " They and their families have an assured, if often a penurious subsistence, provided no unusual or unpropitious circumstances occur, such as the failure of the potatoes or of corn, whereby the earn- ings for threshing are reduced to a minimum, long sickness, or too numerous a family." Unfortunately these "unpropitious circum- stances" are of very frequent occurrence, and the "too numerous family" is the rule rather than the exception. The rates of wages vary naturally in different parts of the country, but in general it may be taken for granted that the worst paid labour is that which is employed on the large corn-growing estates, and particularly those situated in districts like North and North- East Prussia, far removed from centres of industry. While on the Rhine and in Alsace rates of from is. Sd. to is. lod. are usual, in Pomerania, the Mecklenburgs, and the more distant East, 6d. or gd. a day is as much as an average labourer can count on. Taking all the provinces of Prussia together, the wages of out-workers vary from is. 6d. to 2s. per day in summer, and from is. to is. ^d. per day in winter. In 1892 the Association for Social Policy — which began its career in 1872 by declaring that "the rightful interests of the working class as against the egoism of the propertied class should be emphasised with moral pathos," and in 1879 THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 227 approved '* a moderate tariff reform in a financial- political and protective sense" — carefully investi- gated the wages of the agricultural labourers in Prussia generally, and found that the following rates per day ruled in the various provinces of the monarchy : — Summer. Winter. Without With Without With Provinces. board. board. board. board. s. d. s. d. s. d. s. d. East Prussia 2 2 ... I 3 .. 7l West Prussia 2 3 6 ... I 3 •• 7f Pomerania... 2 3 9 ... I 4I .. iii Posen ... I II 3 ... I .. 8 Silesia ... i 6 ... I 2i .. 7^ Brandenburg i g 3 ... I 4l ..10 But in Upper Silesia to-day there are hundreds of farm labourers who only receive 6d. or yd. a day. The average in the west of the Empire is IS. ^d. or IS. 4^. in summer, with a deduction of from 2d. or ^d. per day in winter. Women are paid, at the most, half the wages of men, and children only a quarter. When we are told that in the more progressive and prosperous districts the wages are now as much as 50 per cent, higher than twenty years ago, the first reflection suggested is that the con- dition out of which the labourer has been raised must have been one of simple desperation. For, after all, how far has this 50 per cent, advance brought him ? Quite recently a monograph was pubhshed by Dr. W. Rubow upon the social and agrarian conditions prevalent in the Pomeranian Q 2 228 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. rural commune of Schwessin, with a view to demon- strating the positive injury done to small peasant proprietors and tenant farmers by the corn duties. The writer says that the wages and standard of life of the labouring class in that part of Pomerania are far above the average of the pro- vince, yet, even so, a permanent labourer only earns is. a day the whole year round, with pay- ments in kind which bring his entire pay to ^^27 or £30 ; while the day's wages of forest labourers for exhausting work are is. without extras. On the largest farms a hind receives £8 5s. in money (formerly £5 to £6), several pounds of wool, and material for clothing and shirts of a value of 15s., food which at gd. a day comes to ^13 14s., and a Christmas present of los., making a total of 3^23 4s. A maid earns £"20 4s., made up of £4 los. in money, ^^i los. in goods (three aprons, two lb. of wool, two dresses, twenty-four ells of linen, and four pecks of linseed), ^13 13s. in food, and a Christmas present of los. But such rates are princely as compared with the general run of North Germany. Upon many estates of East Prussia at the present time the entire income of a labourer and his family, inclu- sive of all payments in kind, does not exceed ;^20, and, indeed, the basis of earnings adopted by the insurance authorities, upon which compensation is awarded in case of accident, is in general exactly this sum. A Berlin workman who, from inability to find employment in his trade, hired THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 229 himself for a year upon a Mecklenburg estate, lately put on record his experiences, and a truly lurid light they throw on the social conditions prevalent in that backward part of the country. Of the result of his year's labour he says : — "When I left I received in money i6s. 4^. All the rest of my earnings had been deducted for expenses or for clothing, which I had long ago used up. I could take nothing of this away save two old shirts and two pairs of old stockings. Sixteen shillings and fourpence was the whole of my wages for such long and arduous toil ! I should have earned quite as much in the workhouse, without being compelled to such severe exertion, and I should have been less despised than I was while working as a free man in an honest occupation." To take a case of municipal employment, the labourers on the great irrigation farm belonging to the city of Berlin receive wages varying from is. lod. to 2s. a day in summer and from is. to is. 6d. in winter for men, and is. in summer and lod. in winter for women, beside housing and a piece of land upon which to grow potatoes, the latter having a value of between ^^6 and ;^8. In money value the best paid labourers receive about 14s. a week, the less well paid about 12s. And the hours of labour thus remunerated number 12, 13, and 14 a day, according to the season; for a "normal" working day is fixed, if not strictly observed, viz., from 5.30 a.m. to 7.30 p.m. in summer (with pauses for meals), and from 6.0 to 6.0 in winter. Compare with the foregoing figures the statement of agricultural wages just published by the Board 230 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. of Trade, according to which the average earnings for England, taking the lowest into consideration, are i8s. 6d. (the maximum being 22s.), while a rural labourer can, as a rule, afford to spend 13s. 6^. a week upon the food of his family alone. It is the general rule upon the larger estates that the landlord provides dwellings for his men, charging a small rent, which is counted as wages. Part of the pay takes the form also of a piece of land for potato growing, though the disadvantage of this arrangement is that the labourer is so hard worked that he has little time for work of his own, and unless he has a wife and children who are able to manage it for him the " allotment " runs a chance of being neglected. In general this system of payment in kind is carried to a very unfair length. It is very common for the greater part of a labourer's pay to take the form of corn and other produce, and of course this is cheaper for the landlord, since the Naiuralien which he gives in lieu of money-wages are grown on his estate, and in reckoning their value he takes a fair market price ; but the labourer would much prefer to be paid exclusively in money, so that he might know exactly how much he receives, and make his own arrangements for spending it. It follows, of course, that in so far as agricultural labourers are paid in kind, which for the most part means corn, they neither gain nor lose by the increased price of this commodity, save in so far as that price re-acts upon the prices of other commodities. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 231 As to the housing of the rural labourer, only one opinion is possible : it is for the most part not merely inadequate and primitive, but unworthy of human beings, while the poverty of the people makes domestic comfort out of the question. Says Professor von der Goltz : — " Often one finds only the most needful domestic utensils, and even they are defective, dirty, and scattered in every corner of the rooms. The bed- clothes, upon whose orderliness so much weight is, as a rule, laid, consist of a few tattered rags. The window-panes are seldom all whole, the holes being covered with paper or filled with rags. The children, half naked and dirty, go about unoccupied or lie in bed till noon without being ill. The wife, untroubled by all the disorder and uncleanliness which she sees around her, sits at the stove and cooks the mid-day meal for the family, which, whether abundant or not, always savours of the unappetising surroundings in which it is prepared. Such a picture will meet one, per- haps, in three houses successively on the same estate." But poverty is at the bottom of this deplorable state of things. " There is no denying," adds the Professor, " that, as a rule, the labourers will rather have a couple of bushels of com more a year and put up with their defective housing than the reverse, and that they estimate the value of a house rather by whether it is warm, or can easily be made so, than whether it is healthy or spacious." Where, as sometimes happens, several families are herded together in one house of this kind, the demands alike of convenience, health, and morality are outraged. No wonder that, as the same authority tells us, amongst the children of the 232 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. rural labourers of this class there is a very high rate of mortality, and that adults very often prematurely fall victims to consumption. So, too, Pastor Quistorp, writing of Pomerania, says : — " It is true that the rural labourer does not inhabit a damp cellar or a cold garret, but lives comfortably on the flat earth. Yet that is not the only require- ment of a human habitation. Undoubtedly the Christian disposition of those landed proprietors who are earnestly concerned to provide their employees with healthy and roomy dwellings worthy of human beings should be acknowledged with gratitude, but the great majority of the homes of rural labourers may well be described in the words of their owners : 'They are good enough for the hands.' These dwell- ings are, as a rule, so low and small that where there is a fairly numerous family an intolerable atmosphere is caused, particularly at nights ; the dusty earthen floor is in general so uneven that the labourer's children need special protecting angels in such homes ; the walls are usually made of clay or of thin lath and plaster, so that the massive cattle stalls and barns of the landowner look much warmer and more comfortable than such abodes." ^ A Berlin journal recently described the homes of East Prussian rural labourers in still more realistic fashion as follows : — " The houses are small and dilapidated, and the walls falling in through age, being built in a very primitive manner of clay and wood. The owner hardly does anything at all in the way of repairs ; the labourers themselves have to do all the necessary patching. No wonder, therefore, that the wind whistles unhindered through every niche and cranny, 1 a Die soziale Not der landlicher Arbeiter," Leipzig, i8gi. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 233 and that rain and snow sweep through the rent roof of straw. For each family there is but one small, narrow living room, with a bedroom and a little lumber room. The fioor is of clay, uneven and full of holes ; a floor of brick is regarded as a luxury. The rifts in the walls are stopped up with rags, pieces of turf, &c. ; the windows have long been broken, and the holes are either covered with paper or are filled with rags, moss, or wisps of straw. The internal arrangements correspond — a couple of rickety chairs, a table, the indispensable ' settle,' and the clumsy bedsteads. The limited space is naturally insufficient to afford to the inmates sleeping accommo- dation suited either to rational or moral ideas, especially where there is a large family. Should there be a lodger, and he has to sleep on the floor, perhaps with hens for company, he must not be sur- prised if the rain trickles down upon his head or the snow drifts an inch thick upon his bed-cover. When the frugal meals are being eaten it is no rare thing for sand and pieces of earth to fall through the holes in the rude plank ceiling if the hens should be scratching above. It is by the provision of ' free dwellings ' of this kind that the landowners manifest their much-vaunted solicitude for their labourers. In reality, the pigstyes of the agrarians east of the Elbe are far better fitted up than the miserable huts of the day labourers." The landowners, against whom responsibility for this state of things is alleged, plead perpetual impoverishment, though they have now for a quarter of a century had the benefit of pro- tective duties. There is, however, a great deal of truth in the words of a German critic of the agrarian movement, who says : — " Instead of meeting foreign competition, helped as it is by the use of the most advanced technical 234 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. improvements, by the intelligent management of their estates, the Junkers fall back, with lamentation, upon the support of the State in the form of protective duties and export premiums ; and instead of paying and treating their labourers decently, training them to greater productivity, and interesting them in their work, they do exactly the opposite, and build their expectations upon reactionary coercive measures which shall bring the labouring masses still further under their heel. A well-paid and energetic labour- ing class would at once put an end to the labour problem on the land, not simply because it would be able to work in general more efficiently than the present exhausted helots, but because it would facili- tate the extended use of machinery, now comparatively little employed in agricultural operations. At present it is naturally difficult to procure good and capable labourers for this machinery, but the blame rests entirely with the large proprietors, and particularly with the Junkers, who have done everything they could to make it impossible for intelligent workmen to live on the land." Unfortunately, the relationship between the landowner and his labourers is not in general a friendly one. As respect is lacking on one side, so is confidence on the other. " The feeling that because of their social position they are regarded and treated contemptuously by those from whom they earn their bread weighs like an alp upon the rural labouring population." So writes a Pome- ranian pastor in a study of the agricultural labourer,^ though the words apply equally to other parts of the country where the system of 1 W. Quistorp, "Die soziale Not der landlicher Arbeiter," Leipzig, 1891. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 235 great estates prevails. At an election meeting held in East Prussia in 1903 by Prince Dohna, a scene was created when, at the end of the speeches, a Chief Forester got upon his feet and, ascending the tribune, proceeded in quiet but earnest language to say that while he had no sympathy whatever with Socialistic views, he was bound to say that, judging by his own experience, if Social Democracy was growing in that district as in others, the blame must be laid to the charge of the large landowners, whose treatment of their " people " (Leute) created sympathy for the teaching of that party. " The Social Democrats," he proceeded, " are re- proached with desiring to abolish religion, but what is the state of religion in most parts of the country ? Scripture says ' Six days shalt thou labour, and on the seventh rest,' but can a farm labourer keep that commandment ? What Social Democracy says about the standard of life of the rural population contains a certain amount of truth. One man comes to me and says, ' My landlord will lend me no horses on a week-day wherewith to work my field, and I have to do it on Sunday.' Another comes and says, ' I should have by right fuel free, but I get none.' Such a man comes to the foresters and asks if he may gather fallen wood in the forest, and when has that to be done ? Again on Sunday, since the man with his family has to work all the week for his landlord. I fear," added this official, " that Social Democracy will make good use of abuses like these, and attain success in its agitation by means of them." At the close of this unlooked-for addendum to a hitherto harmonious gathering. Prince Dohna 236 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. himself had to admit that in the treatment of labourers on the land there was *' much that was improper" — a mild way of putting a truth whose bearing upon the political thought and aspirations of the rural classes of German}^ both peasants and labourers, is vital. As an illustration of the social position of the rural labourer in North Germany, the following sample labour contract, as now enforced upon Mecklenburg estates, may be quoted : — "The labourer must work faithfully, diligently, and obediently for his employer and his representa- tives, and must use his best endeavours to cause his wife, children, and dependents similarly to conduct themselves. He undertakes only to work for . . . and to come daily to work unless hindered by sickness, in return for which his employer binds himself to give him work all the year round. "The labourer receives : (i) A house with necessary stallage, for which he is to pay a rent of £1 3s. Such small repairs to the house or stall as mending floors and walls, whitewashing, replacing window panes, and the like must be done by the labourer himself, material of stone, wood, clay, and lime being supplied to him free. The re-setting of stoves is done at the cost of the employer, but the labourer must keep them in order at his own cost. (2) A garden of about sixty square rods, so far as it goes with the house. (3) Potato and linseed land in the open field to the extent of eighty square rods. In the event of his absenting himself in summer, the labourer will only be granted tlie use of the garden, and no land for potatoes and linseed. (4) Pasturage and forage for one cow, and forty square yards of land for the cultivation of cattle turnips or potatoes, which land the labourer must work himself. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOURER. 237 " Permission to keep one breeding goose, with pas- turage on the fallow for the geese. The labourers must provide their own herdsmen, and each labourer must supply to his employer at Michaelmas a young fat goose of at least ten pounds weight. " Two cartloads of fir-wood and 5,000 turves, or more wood equal to the same, by way of wages for fuel-cutting and preparing ; loading and unloading to be done by the labourers free, but carting to be done at the cost of the employer. " Brandy money for the harvest — ^s. for the labourer and IS. 6d. for his help. *' Free medical attendance and medicine for himself and his family in case of sickness, but entirely at the discretion of his employer. " Daily wages for every day of actual work — where the work is not done by piece — as follows for himself and his help : From October 25th to March ist, 2^d. and 4 lb. of rye ; from April ist to June 30th, y^d. and 4 lb. of rye; from July ist to x\ugust 31st, lod. and 4 lb. of rye ; from September ist to October 24th, y^d. and 4 lb. of rye. The labourer's wife receives for washing, &c., 6d. a day, and for outdoor work — from October 24th to March 31st, id. per hour ; from April ist to May 31st, i^d. per hour ; from June ist to August 31st, i^d. per hour ; from September ist to October 24th, ihd. per hour. The time occupied in going to and from work is not to be reckoned. The wife must on demand do the milking, and she will receive i^d. each time. " Threshing pay. — The corn is threshed as far as possible by machine, and as wages is given the seventeenth bushel in case of hand threshing, and the twenty-fifth in case of machine threshing. This pay is divided amongst all the labourers engaged in the work In machine threshing the labourer, should he have no help, must cause his wife to work instead, or arrange for a substitute with the other workers, or receive proportionately less pay in corn. The calculation is for at least eight labourers. 238 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. " The labourer undertakes to supply for farm use sixteen besoms, receiving 6d. as pay, and to spin 6 lb. of tow, to set a brood hen, and to perform other small services as hitherto. The eggs for hatching are supplied by the estate ; should more than three- fourths yield birds, the labourer receives 3d. for each in excess of that number, but if they yield fewer, he must pay yL for each one missing. " The labourer may not, without previous sanction, take into his house for any period whatever any per- sons not employed on the estate on pain of a fine of IS. per night per person. " The hours of work are from 6 a.m. to 8 p.m., and on the short days of the year from daylight till dark. An hour and a half is allowed for dinner, though in busy seasons only an hour, or so much time as is necessary for eating ; for breakfast and tea twent}' minutes or half an hour, though no one may leave his place of work, still less go home, at these intervals without special permission." PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 239 CHAPTER XIV. PROTECTION AND TAXATION. There remains to be considered the strictly fiscal aspect of Protection, i.e., the place of customs duties in the revenue of the Empire and the incidence of these duties upon the population. In treating the first of these questions I naturally leave untouched the whole subject of Imperial expenditure as one which belongs to the domain of domestic policy and has no direct bearing upon the general problem of Protection. How far the financial intentions of the revision of economic policy undertaken in 1879 have been realised, may be explained in a few words. To this end it will be necessary to retrace our steps for a moment. Up to that year the Government had been secured a revenue from customs and excise, for the purposes of the Empire, of nearly ;£"5,7oo,ooo a year, and it was estimated that the new tariff would give a net additional return of :£'3>5oo>ooo> making in all ;£'9,200,ooo. The calcu- lation was arrived at in this way. The value of imported goods in 1877 was 3,877,000,000 marks, but goods to the value of 2,853,000,000 marks were free of duty. Bismarck estimated that under the new tariff half of these free imports would be taxed, 240 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. and assuming an average tax of 5 per cent. ad valorem, he counted on an additional revenue of 70,000,000 marks. But ;^g, 250,000 was more than the Reichstag was wilHng to entrust the Chancellor with, and for a time the Tariff Bill seemed to have struck against an insuperable obstacle. Even the parties of Protection, ready though they were to keep the Empire in funds, insisted that these funds should allow of no extravagance and that the Imperial Diet should retain its old power over the purse. To this attitude was due the so-called Frankenstein Clause, which originated with the Ultramontanes, and was adopted July 15th, 1879, providing that the Empire was to retain only 130,000,000 marks (;^6,50o,ooo) of the revenue from the customs and excise duties, and to return the remainder to the individual States in proportion to their matricular contributions, in other words, according to popu- lation. In that way the reliance upon the old obnoxious system of "grants in aid " was formally perpetuated, and the Chancellor's cherished pro- ject of an independent, self-supporting Empire was once again frustrated. But beggars cannot be choosers, and Bismarck in asking for more elasticity in Imperial finance had asked for too much. He surrendered the point rather than imperil the Bill. Up to the year 1893 the grants which the Empire was able to make to the States out of the customs revenue exceeded — and thus practically PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 241 nullified — the matricular contributions. During the ten years 1883-1893 the amount so distributed was £24,300,000. Then came a period of deficits. In 1893 the increase of the peace strength of the army threw the Empire in an increased degree upon State relief, and in the financial year 1893- 1894 the matricular contributions exceeded the customs grants to the extent of £"2,000,000. Hence new proposals of Imperial taxation were devised to restore the balance by providing the Empire with an additional £5,000,000 of revenue, and side by side with these a modification of the Frankenstein Clause, providing that out of the proceeds of Imperial taxation a minimum of £2,000,000 should be passed to the States after deduction of the sum of the matricular con- tributions in any one year. The project fell to the ground for the time being. In 1894 the pro- posal was altered to the effect that for the coming five years the Empire should bind itself not to require from the States more contributions than would be covered by the grants legally due to them in virtue of the Frankenstein Clause. This pro- posal likewise failed to secure the approval of the Reichstag, which objected that it would have made the Imperial taxation too easy and too auto- matic to be safe, and would virtually have allowed the Federal Council and the Chancellor to dis- pense with the formality of Parliamentary votes. Then for a time the greater buoyancy of the Imperial revenues seemed to make the question of p.G. R 242 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. reform less urgent. In the fiscal year 1894-1895 the matricular contributions exceeded the grants in aid to the extent of ^725,000, but in the two following years, on the other hand, the grants exceeded the contributions. In the year 1896- 1897 the Empire was empowered by a special law to retain ^Tg, 000,000 instead of ;£'6,5oo,ooo, owing to exceptional non-recurring expendi- ture on the army, navy, and the colonies, so that only £100,000 remained out of the taxes for the States when the matricular contributions had been deducted. In later years Imperial finance has gone from bad to worse, until now deficits are systematic. Moreover, these deficits would have been more frequent and more serious had not the Empire covered its needs by prodigal borrowing. The Empire only began to indulge in the luxury of being in debt in 1876 ; by 1888 its loans had reached £36,000,000 ; and they now exceed £155,000,000, while the debts of the federal States have also largely increased in the meantime, until the aggregate of Empire and States has reached £680,000,000. Nevertheless, passing in review the twenty-four years 1880 to 1904, the States fourteen times received back in grants more than they gave to the Empire in contributions, to an aggregate amount of £27,150,000, and paid in eleven years more than they received to the aggregate amount of £7,300,000, a balance in favour of the States of £19,850,000, against which must, of course, be PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 243 placed the disadvantage that they have made over to the Empire many sources of revenue which otherwise would have stood them in good stead. The latest endeavour to reform Imperial finance is seen in the Finance Reform Bill now before the Reichstag. The Government propose to abandon altogether the Frankenstein compro- mise ; they ask that in future the whole of the revenue from customs duties shall be ear-marked for Imperial purposes, and that the States shall share in the excise duties on spirit, which realise about £5,000,000, while under the obligation as hitherto to make good the Empire's yearly deficits by the old matricular contributions. It is further proposed that contingent surpluses shall not be regarded in any distribution of revenue to the States, but shall form a fund out of which to meet extraordinary expenditure for which pro- vision may not be made in the yearly Budgets. The great objection to this arrangement from the constitutional standpoint is that it would make the Government less dependent than before upon Parliamentary control, inasmuch as taxes once legalised cannot be repealed save with the assent of the Federal Council and the Emperor, who would not easily be persuaded to relinquish any existing source of revenue except in exchange for a better. While, thus, the fiscal aspect of the question is still beset with difficulties, it must be unhesitatingly conceded that so far as mere productiveness R 2 244 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. goes the customs duties have altogether ful- filled the expectation based upon them : they have yielded a large and increasing revenue, and if that revenue has not proved sufficient the reason lies with the unforeseen expansion of the Empire's liabilities and the tendency of its spending depart- ments to outrun their means, an experience which is not by any means peculiar to Germany. Hence the comment of a Free Trade critic. Dr. Schaffle, " The duties have been a complete fiscal success," must be unreservedly endorsed. In 1874 the revenue from customs and excise duties realised £12,324,400, but in 1893-1894 £"31,045,990, an increase of £"18,713,550 ; and in 1903-1904 £"40, 512, 600, a further increase of £"9,466,610, and more than threefold the revenue of thirty years before. That considerations of revenue influenced the Government in the latest revision of the tariff may be concluded from the fact that over £5,000,000 is expected to accrue to the Trea- sury as a result of the increased corn duties alone, 447 per cent, falling to wheat, 13 per cent, to rye, 8'8 to oats, 147 to barley, I4'7 to maize, 1*8 to lentils, and 7*4 to rape and rapeseed. No increase of revenue is anticipated from the indus- trial duties, the effect of which, it is expected, will be to restrict imports. Here, however, the question is not exhausted. While the customs tariff has yielded an unex- pectedly large and progressive revenue, there has been a dangerous shifting of the burden of PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 245 taxation more and more from articles of luxury and convenience to those of necessity and even of life. In 1878 the revenue of the principal food duties fell as follows : — , 3 1 '20 per cent, of the whole. and those on other common articles of consumption were : — Coffee Tropical fruits Herrings ... Tobacco Wine Salt Brandy i7"o6 per cent, of the whole. 8-09 4-06 „ „ i"56 In the year i8go the entire incidence of taxation was altered : — Corn (which tool c the first place).. . 28-98 per cent, of the whole. Coffee • ii"97 Petroleum . 11-28 Tobacco ... . 4-86 Wine . 4-86 Lard 2-30 Cattle . 1-85 Brandy . . . 172 While in 1878 corn contributed nothing to the revenue, in 1884 io'94 per cent, of the total duties came from corn, which took the fourth place ; the percentage in 1885 was I2'63 (fourth place), and in 1888 20*24 (fii^st place) ; to-day it still holds the first place with over 30 per cent. The gross revenue from customs duties in 1902 was ;£"26,969,3io against £26,680,300 in 1901, 246 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. £26,055,000 in 1900, 5^25,305,000 in 1899, £25,765,000 in 1898, and £23,745,000 in 1897. A comparison of the two years 1897 and 1902 gives the following results in values and per- centages : — 1897. 1902, Article Taxed. Duty Yielded. Percentage of Total. Duty Yielded. Percentage of Total. Wheat . . Rye Barley . . Maize . . £ 2,140,000 1,430,000 1,065,000 1,015.000 90 6-0 4-5 4"3 £ 3,633,000 1,620,000 1,125,000 720,000 13-5 60 4-2 27 /5, 650, 000 23-8 ;^7,o98,ooo 26*4 Coffee (raw) . . Meat (fresh and prepared) . . 3,416,000 435.000 12-7 1-6 2.720,000 420,000 "■5 So, too, petroleum for light yielded in 1902 a revenue of £2,935,000 or 10*9 per cent, of the whole, against £2,765,000 or ii*6 per cent, in 1897. Taking the duties in groups, as classified in the official returns, the following was the estimated yield in 1902, with the percentage of the whole in each case : — £ Percentage. Comestibles other than corn (groceries and tro- pical produce generally) 10,729,000 ... 3978 Corn and other produce of the land 8,336>78o ... 30-91 Hops 20,148 ... o-o8 PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 247 Cattle Animals and animal pro- ducts not otherwise specified Iron and iron goods Earths, ores, precious metals, and asbestos . . . Instruments, machines, and vehicles ... Copper and other base metals not otherwise named, and goods of the same Zinc and zinc alloys, and goods of the same ... Tin, and goods of the SH.nic ••• ••• ••• Lead, and goods of the sariie ••• ••• ••• Hardware (ironmongery) Petroleum and other mineral oils (light and lubrication) Oils and other kinds of tat ... ... . • • Timber and wood ware . . . Cotton and cotton goods Wool and woollen goods Silk and silk goods Linen yarn and linen goods ... Clothing and personal linen Leather and leather goods Furriery Glass and glass goods ... Earthenware Stones and stone ware ... Paper and paper goods ... I 300,037 Percentage fll 156,800 292,144 ... 0-58 ro8 2,201 O'OI 100,369 - 0-37 31,273 9" 1 2 1,917 O'OI 1,295 O'OI 479 99,218 O'OO ... 0-37 3,571,300 ... 13-24 916,364 950,229 424,558 234.145 210,999 ... 3'49 ••• 3"52 ••• 1-57 ... 0-87 078 78,808 0'29 78,601 109,016 4,820 62,585 31,513 21,682 51,268 0"29 0*40 0-02 0*23 0-I2 o-o8 o-ig 248 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. £ Percentage. 42,043 9-15 Caoutchouc and gutta- percha, and goods of the same Drugs, apothecary's, and dye stuffs Soap and perfumery Straw and wicker work . . . Horse and human hair, and goods of same, feathers, and bristles ... Wax-cloth, muslin, and silk Brushes, &c. Candles ... Playing cards How the pressure of taxation has changed since Protection was introduced may further be shown by a table giving the relative percentage of total revenue raised at different times upon some of the commonest articles of use : — 38,970 .. 21,725 .. . 0-15 . o-o8 31,518 •• 0'12 7,705 •• 6,096 .. 0-03 0-02 3,010 .. O'OI 1,731 •• 84 .. 0"0I 0"00 1S7S. 1890. 1902. Per cent, of the whole. Per cent, of th i whole. Per cent, of th e whole. Coffee 31 20 Corn 28-98 Corn 30-91 Tobacco . . 1 7 "06 Coffee . . 11-97 Coffee ... 12-7 Wine 8-09 Petroleum 11-28 Petroleum 10-9 Tropical Tobacco . . 10-84 Tobacco . . 97 Fruits . . 4'io Wine 4-86 Wine 2*5 Salt 4 '06 Timber . . 3 "95 Timber . . 30 Woollen Lard 2-30 Lard 2-0 Goods . . 3'44 Iron 2-07 Meat 1-6 Cotton Cattle . . 1-85 Brandy . . i-o Goods . . 2*25 Brandy . . 1-72 Herrings . . 1-94 1-84 — Roots 74'3i Brandy . . 1-56 80-82 I Der cent. per cent. 75-54 per cent. PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 249 Figures like these, without reducing them to further detail, give a plain indication of the incidence of taxation in Germany ; it falls over- vvhelmingl}' not upon luxuries, as with the more truly revenue system of duties in vogue in Eng- land, but on the first needs and utilities of life. This appears still more clearly when we inquire what these taxes on food and convenience mean in the concrete. Naturally the corn tax suggests itself first. Estimates vary as to the sacrifice which this tax entails on the community. Under the old duties, as reduced for treaty purposes, the Treasury raised by taxation of all kinds of grain eight and a third million pounds in 1902, but this was only a part of the tribute which the duties entailed. Assuming that the price of corn was not increased beyond the amount of the duty, it has been estimated that the total sacrifice imposed on the community would not fall far short of 5^40,000,000, or 14s. ^d. per head of the popu- lation. Some German writers have even placed the entire tribute levied in the interests of agriculture as high as ^^'so, 000,000 a year, and Professor Lotz estimates that the minimum duties of the new tariff will entail a further yearly impost in the one item of corn alone of 5^i5j75o>ooo. Yet the proportion of this large tribute which finds its way into the Treasury is very small. That corn is actually made dearer by taxation is proved by comparison with free markets. Thus 250 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. the price of wheat in BerKn from 1886 to i8go was 31S. yd. per ton higher than in London ; from iSgi to 1895 it was 46s. higher, and from 1895 to 1899 it was 34s. 6d. higher, and the duties during these three periods were 30s. increasing to 50S., 50S. falHng to 35s., and 35s. The steadiness of the increase in the cost of agricultural food- stuffs generally which set in after the second revision of the tariff is shown by the following comparison of average prices in twenty-three Prussian markets : — Per Ton. 1892. 1891. 1890. .1889. 1888. Wheat Rye Barley Potatoes . . £ s. d. 980 8 i5 7 15 340 £ s. d. II I 10 7 870 3 13 £, s. d. 9 II 880 820 290 £. s. d. 920 7 15 7 10 2 12 ;£ ^. d. 8 14 6 14 6 14 2 10 Per Kilogramme. Marks. Marks. Marks. Marks. Marks. Beef 1-28 1-28 1-27 ri8 ri4 Mutton 1-24 1-28 1-26 1-17 i'i3 Veal 125 127 1-24 1-15 1-07 Pork 1-35 132 1-42 1-31 ri7 Butter 2-30 2'24 2 "23 226 2'12 Lard I 64 1-65 174 r6i 1-50 Since then the price of corn has fallen con- siderably, but there has been a continuous increase PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 251 in other articles of food during the past decade, as witness : — Per Kilogramme. Per Kilo- gramme. Per lb. 1892. 1902. Increase. • Marks. Marks. Marks. Beef Veal Mutton • . Pork 123 ri6 1-27 1-22 I -So I -So I -80 I -60 0-57 0-64 0-53 0-38 5¥- 3d. 2d. Here we have the obvious explanation of the fact attested b}' the Board of Trade, who in the fiscal Blue Book show that the cost of living "has fallen very much less " in Germany during the twenty-five years 1877 to igoi than in this country. Taking igoi as the test and 100 as the index- number, the movement of prices of food has been as follows : — TJ nited Kingdom. Germany. 1877 . . 143 ••• .. 115 1878 . . 134 ... no 1879 . . 128 ... no 1880 . . 136 ... .. 114 I88I 133 in 1882 . • 133 ... 109 1883 . . 133 ... 107 1884 . 122 .. 98 1885 . III .. 98 1886 . . 105 ... 95 1887 . 100 95 1888 . 100 .. 96 252 PROTECTION IN GERMANY. United Kingdom. Germany 1889 104 104 i8go 102 •• 105 1891 .. 104 . .. 116 1892 .. 104 . 112 1893 ... .. 98 . 97 1894 ..• 95 • 95 1895 ... 91 . .. 96 1896 ... .. 87 . 95 1897 ... 94 . lOI 1898 ... 100 .. 103 1899 ... 93 . .. 98 1900 .. 96 . ... 98 1901 100 100 Thus up to 1900 there was a fall of 49 points in the United Kingdom against one of 17 points in Germany. The Board of Trade investigators come to the conclusion that during the quin- quennium 1897 — igoi "a German workman has been able to purchase as much food of the kind to which he is accustomed for 100 marks as he could get previously for 112 marks, while the English workman has been able to make 100 shillings go as far in purchasing food as 140 shillings would have gone twenty years before." What the corn tax pure and simple means to the working classes will be better understood when it is remembered how large a part bread plays in the economy of the German household. Professor Walther Lotz estimates that 16 per cent, of the workman's income is spent in bread alone, though in many places the percentage is PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 253 larger ; thus the average in Halle is 20 per cent., and amongst the weavers of Zittau it is from 25 to 30 per cent., though amongst the better- paid artisans of Nuremberg it has been found to be but 9*2 per cent. Taking, however, a con- sumption of 16 per cent, as fair for the working classes generally, and further assuming even wages of i8s. per household, it follows that 2s. lod. per week is expended a head, and of this 2S. 10^. yd. is tax paid to the State. In addition there are the duties upon other food- stuffs and indispensable domestic requisites. How such duties work out, on the basis of the last available complete return of revenue, is shown by the following figures : — Yearly tax Yearly tax per head of per house- Article taxed. the popula- hold of five tion. persons. s. d. s. d. Wheat and rye ... ... i io| ... 9 42 Coffee I 2| ... 6 o^ Petroleum i o| ... 5 2| It is estimated that the duty now paid on every shilling's purchase is as follows : — On lard 2|^., on butter and margarine i^d., on baked goods 4^d., on coffee and surrogates 5f^., on cocoa and choco- late 3|^., on cooking oil 2d., on eggs |(i., on cheese ifi., on lard i^d., on rice 2^d., on tea y^d., on salted herrings i^d. To put the matter otherwise, taking customs duties and excise taxes together, the taxation which at present 254 PROTECTION IN GERMANY falls upon commodities of commonest use is as follows : — Bread Meat Lard Bacon Salt Sugar Rice Per pound. .. H id. ^d .. Id. .. lU. .. id. The population of the Empire has grown far beyond expectations since 1871, but its taxation has progressed at an even greater rate. In that year the customs duties cost every inhabitant (man, woman, and child) 2s. i0(i. per annum, and in 1878 the rate had fallen to 2S. y^d. ; in 1888 it had reached 6s. 6d., in 189 1 8s. i^^., and last year it was 9s. 8^. per head. The similar tax in England was I2S. 8^. Taking customs and excise together, the advantage is apparently still further on Germany's side, and arguing from these bald figures, a German economist of the leading rank, Professor Adolf Wagner, has seriously contended that the German taxpayer, with his yearly tribute of 15s. ^d. in customs and excise duties, is better off than the Englishman with his ^^i 5s. id. and still more than the Frenchman with his ^^i 12s. gd.^ It would be just as reasonable to contend that the man who on an income of £500 pays income tax of ;£"20 is better off than the man who pays £"50 1 I give the figures as published, unable to analyse their composition. PROTECTION AND TAXATION. 255 upon an income of -^1,000. Obviously the height of taxation must be estimated relatively to the sum of the national and individual income. Not only so, but an equally important question, in comparing the incidence of taxation, is the cha- racter of the taxes paid — whether on the necessities or on the superfluities of consumption. With the facts which have been given on both these points before him, the reader will be able to form his own conclusions. To carry the inquiry further into the domain of direct taxation would hardly be pertinent to our purpose, though there is room for reflection in the fact that while in England there is exemp- tion from income tax below an income of 5^150 the exemption stops at ;^45 in Prussia, and at 3^20 in Saxony, with the result that a large section of domestic servants are regularly assessed to this tax twice over — once by the State and again by the municipality, whose " class tax " is based on the income tax, since in estimating their income the equivalent of board and lodging is taken into consideration. Thus a servant with money wages of ;^20 or upwards may pay from 12s. to 20s. a year in State and municipal taxes, according to locality. ^-'^^/TY INDEX. -♦ — Agrarian Movement and Agrarian League, the, 128 — 140 Agricultural Labourer, Condi- tion of the, 224 — 238 Agricultural Protection and its Effect, 72, 73. 84, 85, 104— 106, 128 — 140, 142 — 160, 202 —223 Altenstein, von, 16 Bismarck, Prince, Economic Views, 21, 63 — 66, 69 — 74, 88, 89 ; Theories of Taxation, 41—57 Bohmert, Victor, 24 Brentano, Professor Lujo, 127 Bulow, Count von, (1) 13, 16; (2) 140, 143, 147, 152, 154. 157. 158 Camphausen, Otto, 25, 60 Canada, Tariff War with, 122 —124 Caprivi, Count von, gS, 106 — iiS, 127, 130, 143, 147, 1S3, 210, 217 Chambers of Commerce, Testi- mony of, 80, 91, 92, 124, 162. 163 Colonial Movements, Early Prussian, 5 Commercial Treaties, 21, 47, 68, 85, 108—127 Commercial Treaty Era. 98 — 127 Corn Prices, 86, 88, 89, 96, 99, 136, 206, 212, 213, 250 Creuzbacher, G., 197 Customs Tariffs of 1879, 26 — 40, 58—77 ; of 1885, 87—95 ; of 1887, 95—97; of 1902, 141 — 160 Customs Union, the, 17 — 25 Delbruck, M. F, R., 25, 39. 59. 72 Dolma, 16 Dumping, 71, 170, 175—177 Emigration Returns, 180, 181 Exports and Export Trade, 7, 32 — 34. 81, 101—106. 125, 126. 166 — 169 Faucher, Julius, 23 Food, Cost of, 82, 192 — 199, 250, 251 ; Consumption by Working Classes, 192 — 199 Frederick the Great, Economic Policy of, 3—5, 115, 213 Frederick William II., 7 ; III., 9. 13 Free Trade Markets, German Trade in, 165, 166 Free Trade Tendencies, 21 — 25, 183, 184 French War, Effect of, 29, 30 Gneisenau, 16 Goltz, Professor von der, 225, 231 P.O. 258 INDEX. Hammerstein, Baron von, 206 Hardenberg and Stein, Laws of, 9 — 16 Heydt, August von der, 25, 60 Hirschfeld, F., 195 Hohenlohe, Prince, 140, 143, 217, 218 Humboldt, Wilhelm von, 13, 16 Huskisson, William, 16 Imperial Taxation, 49 — 57, 69. 70, 239—243 Imports and Import Trade, 81, loi — 106, 125, 126, 168, 169 Industrial Protection, 71, 146, 148, 161 — 184 Industry, The Beginnings of German, 2 Kanitz, Count, and Corn Monopoly, 136—138, 218 Labour, Condition of: Indus- trial, 185 — 201 ; Agricultural, 224 — 238 Lette, W. A.. 23 List, Friedrich, 15 Lotz, Professor Walther, 39, 75, 149, 178, 249 Matlekovits, 96, 214 Mercantile System, the, 3, 8 Michaelis, Otto, 23 Miquel, Dr., 205 Moritz, Dr. Eugen, 78, 164, 171. 183 NlEBUHR, 16 PiCKFORD, 24 Prince Smith, John, 23, 24 Protection, the German Tradi- tion, I Protection and Agriculture, 72, 73, 84, 85, 104—106. 128 — 140, 142 — 160 Protection and Taxation, 239 —255 Protection and Trade, 100 — 106, 161 — 184 Protective Tariffs of 1879, 26 — 40, 58—75 ; of 1885, 87—95 ; of 1887, 95 — 97; of 1902, 141 — 160 Prussian Fiscal Traditions, 1—25 QuisTORP, Pastor, Testimony of, 232 Reaction of 1879, Protec- tionist, 26 — 40 Richter, Eugen, 124 Rubow, Dr., 21S, 219 Russia, Tariff War with, 119, 120 ScHAFFLE, Professor Albert, 21, 22, 27, 94, 98 — 106, 182, 206, 244 Scharnhorst, 16 Schon, 16 Schultze - Gavernitz, G. von, 199 Schulz, Dr. A., 204 Schulze-Delitzsch, 23 Small Farming, Value of Sys- tem of, 220 — 223 Smith, Adam, 10, 15 Soetbeer, 96 Stein and Hardenberg Laws, the. 9 — 16 Syndicates, the, 170—173 Tariff of 1879, 26 — 40, 58 — 77; of 18S5, 87—95; of 1887. 95—97; of 1902, 141 — 160 Tariff Duties, 20—25, 76, 90, 91.95. 156 Tariff War with Russia, 119; Canada, 122 — 124 Taxation, Prince Bismarck's Theories of, 41 — 57 Taxation and Protection, 239 —255 INDEX. 259 Thirty Years' War, Effect of, 2,3 Trade and Protection, 100 — 106, 161 — 184 Treitschke, H. von, 31 Varnbuler, Baron von, 62 Wages : Industrial, 82, 83, 97, 171, 186 — 191 ; Agricultural, 225 — 227 Wagner, Professor Adolf, 254 William I., Emperor, and Protection, 39, 77 Wirth, Max, 23 Working Man, Condition of the Urban, 185 — 201 ; Rural, 224—238 THE END. BRADBURY, AGNEW, & CO. I-D , PRINTERS, LONDON AND TONBRIDGE. Demy 8vo. Cloth, 256 pp. and Index. 3s. 6d. net. ELEMENTS OF THE FISCAL * PROBLEM * * * BY L. G. CHIOZZA MONEY, Fclloxv of the Royal Statistical Society ; Author of "British Trade and the Zollvercin Issue," etc.; Statistical Secretary to the Free Trade Union. Westminster Gazette : — " It is impossible for anyone who reads this book to complain that the Free Trade doctrine is abstract, antiquated, or visionary. Never was a case presented in a more modern, concrete, or practical form." Sheffield Independent : — " Mr. Money's book must be reckoned as one of the very best practical expositions of our Free Trade policy the controversy has given us." Birmingham Express : — '• Every student of the fiscal question should obtain a copy of Mr. L. G. Chiozza Money's book. ... It is written in a clear and comprehensive style." Spectator : — " We do not know of any book of the same length which contains such a mass of accurate and relevant information upon the main question at issue, and especially upon the nature 01 our imports and exports." LONDON : P. S. KING & SON. ORCHARD HOUSE. WESTMINSTER. SECOND EDITION WITH TWO ADDITIONAL SECTIONS. Demy 8vo. Cloth. 436 pp. tOsm 6tSm net THEORIES OF PRODUCTION AND DISTRIBUTION. A HISTORY OF THE THEORIES OF PRODUCTION AND DISTRI- BUTION IN ENGLISH POLITICAL . . ECONOMY FROM 1776-1848. . . BV EDWIN CANNAN, M.A., LL.D., Appelated Teacher of Economic Theory in the University of Loadoa. CHAP, CONXENTS. I. The Wealth of a Nation. II. The Idea of Production. III. The First Requisite of Production— Labour. IV. The Second Requisite of Production— Capital. V. The Third Requisite of Production— Land. VI. The Idea of Distribution. VII. Pseudo-Distribution. VIII, Distribution Proper. IX. General Review: Politics and Economics. Index, WESTMINSTER: P. S. KING & SON, ORCHARD HOUSE. STATISTICAL STUDIES RELATING TO NATIONAL PROGRESS IN WEALTH AND TRADE Since 1882. A PLEA FOR FURTHER INQUIRY. By A. L. BOWLEY, M.A., Author of "Elements of Statistics," etc. Cr. 8vo, 2s. net. Daily Chronicle: — "This book constitutes far and away the best unofficial analysis of statistics bearing on the fiscal controversy. Mr. Bowley is much the most competent and scientific of our unofficial statisticians, and, unlike the many experts who have been entertaining us in the newspapers, he is not only a ' statistician, but also a well-read econo- mist who kno.. behind the figures he displays. . . . Mr. Bowley hok no brief for either side, and is rightly emphatic on the limits of the data, especially for comparison with foreign countries ; but, as he I'emarks, so far as they go they show a steady increase of prosperity, and the onus of proof to the contrary lies on the challengers. As a corrective to loose and slipshod argument this book is invaluable." l^ONDON : F». S. KING 6- SON, Orchard Hous^, "Westminster. YB'Sdi RETURN TO the circulation desk of any University of California Library or to the NORTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY BIdg. 400, Richmond Field Station University of California Richmond, CA 94804-4698 ALL BOOKS MAY BE RECALLED AFTER 7 DAYS 2-month loans may be renewed by calling (510)642-6753 1-year loans may be recharged by bringing books to NRLF Renewals and recharges may be made 4 days prior to due date DUE AS STAMPED BELOW JUN 1 6 1995 ?0,000 (4/94)