-'<^'' 1^''- '■V fcrr'?: 'f:M. ^$&-> fyi^ ,j-.-;.'v.- -.-i-.' ^^': ;^'^- 1 .2^ millions of Timber, £\\\ millions of Raw Cotton. It is needless to say that we require all these things for immediate consumption and as materials for our industries, and that we must, for the most part, import them. Another excerpt comprises £,6\ millions of Eggs, £6\ millions of Cheese, £\2 millions of Barley and Oats, £\'j\ millions of Bacon and Hams, ;^20 millions of Wool, i^20^ millions of Butter, £2']\ millions of Meat living and dead, ;^36 millions of Wheat and Wheat Flour. These, indeed, are all products which we could raise or make at home, but we could scarcely provide the whole of them without encroaching seriously on the provision of other things. Take, again, a few of our Exports. There are £^\ millions of Linen Manufactures, ;^ 5 f millions of Ships, £6\ millions of Apparel and Slops, ^17 millions of Machinery, £2\\ millions of Woollen Manufactures and Yarn, £26^ millions of Coal, ;;^29:^ millions of Iron and Steel, £6^ millions of Cotton Manufactures and Yarn. These figures show how much we have specialised in making II. OF FOREIGN TRADE q goods for foreign countries. But a more gratify- ing feature is that the long h'st of our exports shows that, in addition to these great staples, we are exporters of " odds and ends " : it indicates a healthy state of things that there is scarcely an industry one could name which does not export something. Our foreign trade, then, altogether amounts to ;^877,ooo,ooo ; made up of iJ" 5 28,000,000 of Imports, and ;^349,ooo,ooo of Exports (^65,000,000 of these being re-exports). These are values of solid Commodities brought in and taken out over British seas ; and — partly as reflex and consequence — of the 32,000,000 gross tons of shipping i^ the world, we own the half^ How is this foreign trade done? A good deal of the mystery which seems to surround the subject would disappear, if it were realised that it is done /reefy by individual mer- chants and manufacturers in the various countries, working for a profit, with no consideration for 1 The above figures of Imports and Exports, taken from the Statistical Abstract 1903, do not inchide Bullion and Specie, of which we imported, in 1902, ;^2i,629,ooo of gold (^8 millions from South Africa, £^^ millions from India, £^ millions from Australia), and ;,^9, 764,000 of silver (;i^8 millions from the United States), and exported ;,^ 15,409,000 of gold and ^10,716,000 of silver. Nor do they include, either as imports, exports, or re- exports, excisable foreign merchandise transhipped under Bond, (;^ 1 3,683,000). To the imports should be added ;i^5, 380,000 of diamonds from the Cape, not declared to the Customs. It may be noted that fish of British take, landed in the United Kingdom, are not included among imports. The value of these in 1901 was /9,ooo,ooo. lo FOREIGN TRADE AN CHAP. national interests ; and that it would not be done unless there were a profit in it. A sugar merchant here, for instance, appoints an agent abroad and supplies him with samples and quotations. The agent either sends orders at these quotations, or wires home what price he can get. If the price is below the quota- tion, the merchant goes down to Greenock, and sees if he can induce some refiner or other to quote lower. But there is no reason that the refiner should sacrifice his profit because the sugar is wanted for a foreign country. And, although the sugar merchant may do so on occasion, it is only from considerations of future profit. Or, say that the manufacturer is the exporter — as, evidently, he is tending to become. He has not one cost for goods sold at home and another for goods sold abroad. He will sell at cost (including profit) in the one market as in the other. Some- times, indeed, he will sell under this cost abroad in order to " get in," but so he does at home. There is nothing preferable in foreign trade unless he gets a better profit by it, or, it may be, gets his cash more easily, or sells in larger bulk. The motive in both cases, then, is the same — profit. Nor is the method different. A merchant here receives an order from a town in Great Britain, and sends down the goods packed to the railway. By the same post comes an order from New York, and the goods packed are sent down to the harbour. In the latter case, the goods require to be more carefully invoiced and described, and the invoice has sometimes to be sworn to before a II. EXTENSION OF HOME TRADE ii consul as accurate, but this should not be very difficult for an honest man. Nor yet is the way in which payment is made essentially different. In due time, home goods are paid by a cheque ; foreign goods, by a bill of exchange.^ Indeed, in many cases, when goods are put on board ship, the Bill of Lading is given to a bank here, which does not give it up till cash is paid abroad, the bank meantime giving an advance to the exporter to a large proportion of the value. In either case, the sender gets his payment, in British money, through his own bank, and each transaction ends with a payment. The export of goods, again, from other countries to us takes place in exactly the same way — mer- chants and manufacturers, there also, sending out goods for a profit, getting paid in their own money, and the transaction ending with the pay- ment. What we have, then, in international trade is just an extension of home trade. We send goods as naturally to France as we send them across the other channel to Ireland. If there is one thing more prominent than another as to the means of payment in home trade, it is that Gold does not pass between buyer and seller, debtor and creditor. It might ' Without going into the mysteries of banking, it may suffice to say that the reason why payment for foreign goods is not made by cheque is that each country's banking system does not extend be- yond its own shores. / 12 GOLD DOES NOT PASS chap. pass ; but it never occurs to anyone to take this cumbrous method when an easier and more economic one is within everybody's reach, and when there is one great class of traders waiting and anxious to make a profit by arranging pay- ments through their books. Why, then, this persistent assumption on the part of some people that, when goods are sold to foreign countries, they are paid for in gold ? As in home trade, they may be paid for in gold. Gold will pay for them, and sometimes it may be more convenient to pay in gold than in anything else : — it is quite clear, for instance, that gold-pro- ducing countries pay for much of their imports with gold. But it is just as true that they may be paid for in any other kind of goods. It takes a little thinking to realise that, in home trade, payments are made by setting debts against debts, and that this is merely another way of say- ing, "setting goods against goods." You send me ;^ioo worth of goods, and I, for the moment, am in debt, and send you a record of it in the shape of a promise to pay in three months. On the other hand, I send you ;^ioo worth of goods, and you give me a promise to pay in three months. The promises may be bought and sold and pass into other hands ; in any case, they remain in existence as debts for three months. At the end of that time they are brought together and cancel each other.^ What really has happened, ■■It is strong testimony to the literal "trust" which under- lies the credit system that, in the great majority of home transac- tions, the promise is not put in documentary shape at all ; goods are. II. A CONTRA-ACCOUNT IN GOODS 13 of course, is that the one sending of goods has been put in contra-account against the other. So banking is just a vast complex system of contra- accounting — value of goods represented for the moment by documents put to the debit and credit sides of bankers' books. Happily, this need not be dwelt on, because, in international trade, the foundation of the contra-account is quite obvious and prominent. To one standing at Gravesend, and watching the innumerable ships that pass in and out of the Port of London, it must be evident that valuable goods are being brought in and valuable goods are being sent out of the country. All these goods must be paid for. i\.nd if there is, in all countries, a special trade set aside for, and doing almost nothing else than, arranging payments between buyers and sellers, debtors and creditors, it is evident that these valuable cargoes will be set against each other. There are bills drawn from the one side and bills drawn from the other ; these put the values of the goods into figures, and afford documentary records of the transactions ; and these records can be easily set against each other in debtor and creditor account. But, underlying all these records, is the something recorded, and that something is the valuable goods sent either way. As has been said, all these cargoes could be paid sold on customary terms of credit, and paid on a mere reminder that payment is due. Perhaps there is no belter instance of the recognition of a "common interest" and a "general will" among whole peoples than this. 14 EXPORTS PA V FOP IMPORTS CH. ii. for in gold. It is conceivable that there might be a constant current of gold crossing the seas either way. But, as the chief function of gold is not for consumption but for circulation, it would be a singularly futile and wasteful proceeding to send gold oversea, only to get it sent back again. Gold does, indeed, pass between nations : every week, the financial journals tell of so much bullion or so many sovereigns sent out or brought in. But this gold current evidently pursues a course of its own, regulated for the most part by the needs of the nations for bank reserves : instead of making payment, it is, perhaps, more often than not, going counter to the course it would take if it were being sent in payment of goods. If, then, the only object of sending goods abroad is to sell them ; if the only object of selling them is to get paid for them ; if goods cannot be paid in mere promises ; if they are not paid in the universal commodity, gold ; and if, as a rule, no man is conscious of not being paid — why, then, we should naturally expect to find that there is a contra-account in goods : that Imports are paid for and balanced by Exports. CHAPTER III. THE BALANCE OF TRADE. The constant excess in our Imports over our Exports is due to statistical necessities. It is explained, fro?n the side of exports, (i) by shippiftg charges ; (2) by bankers' and other comtiiissions — these two are " invisible exports " : frotn the side of imports, (3) by returns on capital lent and invested abroad ; (4) by boarding expenses, and by some smaller items. Allowing for time and accidental disturbances, there should, apparently, be equivalence in value between the Exports and Imports of a country. No sooner, however, do we get this length in deductive reasoning than we have to face the fact that, according to the last statistics, Spain is the only country whose exports and imports do balance each other. Germany has a balance of Imports over Exports of some £^'j millions; France, some £2}^ millions; Holland, ^^22.4 millions; Belgium, £>\2 millions; Italy, ^^8.7 millions ; Norway, £j millions ; Denmark, £6\ millions ; Sweden, £6 millions ; Portugal, £^ millions ; Japan, £^.Z millions. On the other hand, the United States has a balance of Exports i6 THE BALANCE OF TRADE chap. over Imports of ;^ii8 millions; Russia, £^ millions ; Austro-Hungary, £6 millions ; Egypt, £\.6 millions; Argentine Republic, ;^7. 7 millions; Chili, £1-2) millions ; Uruguay, £\.^ millions.^ This is the phenomenon called the Balance of Trade, of which we hear so much.^ Practically every country has a balance the one way or the other, and, as a rule, the balance is a persistent ^ The above figures are averages of the last five years, taken from the Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries of 1903. ^ The expression Balance of Trade is intelligible ; not so, to modern ideas, the adjective "favourable," applied to a balance of exports over imports, and "adverse" to a balance of imports over exports. The explanation is historical, and rests on the import- ance attached to gold and silver by early mercantilist writers. "Adverse" related to the effect, or supposed effect, of carr}'ing gold and silver out of the country, caused by an excess of imports. The extraordinary importance attached to the precious metals was perhaps justified in times when there were no bankers ; when Europe was starving for a sound currency, and industry hampered by the want of it. All countries took strong measures to attract and retain gold and silver ; even Spain — the depot of these metals — prohibited their export under the most drastic penalties. When in time it was seen that such measures were useless, it was conceived that there was a more natural way of effecting the same object ; if encouragement were given to exports while imports were handicapped, there would tend to be a " favourable balance " — that is, the excess of value would come in gold and silver ; hence bounties on exports and duties on imports. So, said Adam Smith, " the attention of Government was turned away from guarding against the exportation of gold and silver to watch over the balance of trade as the only cause which could occasion any augmentation or diminution of these metals. From one fruitless care it was turned away to another, much more intricate, much more embarrassing, and just equally fruitless." It is notable that, in this regard, duties on imports were not, primarily at least, intended for the protection of home industries so much as for the protection of gold and silver. III. SHIPPING SERVICES 17 and not a passing one. And the state of the case with us is that, taking the average of the last ten years, excluding bullion and specie, our country shows a Balance of Imports over Exports of .^ I 55,000,000, or, taking 1902, .^^ 179,000,000. If, however, exports tend to be equivalent in value to imports, how is this balance to be explained ? I. The first item in the explanation is not very difficult to understand. Those who love things in the concrete might consider what would be the state of imports and exports in Tyre when the Phoenician fleet set sail from the east, with cargoes of dyed wool, gems, and spices, and, after many days, brought back tin and other pro- ducts of the western isles. If the voyage were conducted on commercial principles, the imports would exceed the exports in value. In international as in home trade, payment is made for goods, not only by other goods but occasionally by Services — ^just as a physician may square his butcher's bill by medical attendance on the butcher's family. It happens that there is a trade, and a great trade, which is carried on outside our national boundaries, and, equally, out- side the boundaries of any other nation — on the No Man's Land of the sea. It is peculiarly a British trade. But it has no material product. It is a transport service — the service of ocean carriage, including insurance. It sums up a great number and variety of costs incurred after goods have left our shores, or other shores, as statistical exports, and these costs must be added i8 SHIPPING SERVICES CHAP. to the selling price of the imported goods if other nations are to get our goods, and if we are to get other nations' goods. Where these Services, then, are rendered to foreigners by persons residing in Great Britain, they must be paid for to Great Britain. They are paid, as usual, in goods, and the payment appears as an import against which there is no export recorded in our official trade returns — for, as I say, this trade is carried on outside the national boundaries. It is merely another way of stating this, to say that our Exports are entered F.O.B. and our Imports C.I.F, In the official returns of imports and exports, occur the words : " The values of the Imports represent the cost, insur- ance, and freight ; or, when goods are consigned for sale, the latest sale value of such goods. The values of the Exports represent the cost and the charges of delivering the goods on board the ship, and are known as ' free on board ' values." In other words, our Exports are entered at home prices — that is, free on board ship — the same prices at which they would be delivered to a warehouse in this country. But they appear as Imports in other countries at our home price plus freight and insurance. On the other hand, goods which appear in the official books of other countries as their Exports at their "free on board" price, are entered in our official books as Imports at their foreign or exported price plus freight and insurance. Thus, where our ships carry the goods, the exports will always appear as less than the I. AN INVISIBLE EXPORT 19 imports which pay for them by the amount of the freight and insurance.^ One can see the reason of Sir Robert Giffen's suggestive name for this — " Invisible Exports." Suppose that neither England nor France owned any ships ; that all the trade between the two was conducted by the Channel Islands ; and that these islands did no other foreign trade — as was very much the case with Venice in old days — would it not be true that the Channel Islands' official returns would show all imports and no exports ? And if the Channel Islands' returns were not entered separately, but lumped with the British returns, would there not be a permanent excess in our statistical imports over our statistical exports, while France showed a balance the other way about ? It may be expected, then, that a nation which owns half the world's shipping, and carries for foreigners as well as for British merchants, will be paid a very large sum for this service. The amount was estimated by Gififen, in 1898, as ;^90,ooo,ooo. An independent calculation,^ on ^ A convenient formula for this is as follows : Suppose that freight is 5 per cent, on the value of goods, and that our ships carry the goods both ways, then ^100 worth of our exports appears as ;[^io5 worth of another country's imports, and ^xo'-) worth of the other country's exports appear as^^iio worth of our imports. "^Memoranda, Statistical Tables, and Charts, with reference to various matters bearing on British and Foreign Trcuie and Indus- trial Conditions, p. 99. This is the Blue Book called out by the present fiscal enquiry (Cd. 1761), and published in August, 1903. It should certainly be in the hands of all who wish to make a serious study of the fiscal question. As I shall have constantly to refer to 20 A SECOND INVISIBLE EXPORT CHAP. quite different lines, was put forward by the Board of Trade in 1903, and makes it ^89^ millions.^ This is the first item which explains our appa- rent Balance of Imports. Our exports are really ;^90,ooo,ooo more than the statistical exports shown by the official returns.^ II. There is another Export of Services, or Invisible Export, which works out in the same way. It is not only ships that do business outside the boundaries of our country, but Men. If a journalist, sitting in his study in London, writes an article for a German newspaper, that newspaper has, presumably, to pay him. His export of service goes under a postage stamp, but it, I may, for convenience sake, call it in future references the Board of Trade Blue Book. ^ Gifi'en's calculation was first made in 1882 {Essays in Finance^ Second Series, p. 132), and was revised in 1898 {Royal Statistical Society's Journal, 1899, p. 11). His method was to take the British gross tonnage earnings at ;^I5 and ;i^5, for steamers and sailers re- spectively, at the former date, and at ;^I2 and £i, at the latter. The Board of Trade, on the other hand, took the total exports and im- ports of the principal countries of the world, which are, of course, the same goods valued at points of departure and arrival ; accepted the ;if224,ooo,ooo difference in their value (see p. 41) as represent- ing freights and insurance ; halved this sum to represent our share of the carrying tonnage of the world ; deducted 9 per cent, for colonial ships, and further deducted ^12^ millions for coals and stores purchased abroad, harbour and other dues ; and arrived at the figure of £^0)\ millions. ^ The importance of Shipping as a British export industry may be realised by remembering that ;i{^90, 000,000 is just about the value of our colton and woollen exports combined. III. BANKERS' SERVICES 21 the value of what is contained in the wrapper is not, one may hope, represented by the stamp. If the German paper pays him by sending a couple of guineas' worth of German books, then this is an import of goods, although, as passing through the post it would not appear among official imports. This is merely an illustration of the fact that there are very large classes in this country who perform services for foreigners which have no embodiment in material goods. If one considers what is involved in the statement that London is the clearing house of the world— that a bill or draft on London is the best and most widely known form of international currency — one will under- stand that British bankers, sitting in London, do business all over the world, and that the payment for these services must come in goods, or in other services. But, besides bankers, there are the fire and life insurance companies, and the great army of commission merchants, who do business very much in the same way. Services like these cannot be put into statistical figures — there is no possible means of getting at them — but, the more one considers the magnitude of this business, the more one will be disposed to say that several millions should be added to our statistical exports on this account. One may question the exactness of any figure put on these invisible exports — take a few millions off it, or add a few millions to it. But a country which does half the shipping trade of the world, and is, at the same time, the headquarters 22 INTEREST AND PROFITS chap. of the banking trade of the world, must have a very large sum due to it by way of payment, and this must come in some valuable shape. If it does not come in imports of goods or services, in what does it come? Or where does this " invisible " export appear as a statistical export ? III. There still remains a good deal to make up the Balance. But there still remains a large department of international relations which has not yet been taken into account. Nations buy from and sell to each other. But they are also connected with each other as debtors and creditors. Let us see how this affects imports and exports. The third item of the balance is due to the fact that we have, notoriously, been lending to all the world and investing capital all over the world, and that the returns come home annually in the shape of goods. How much our capital lent and invested abroad may amount to, is a matter of rather rough calculation. It is variously estimated from ^2,000,000,000 to ;^2, 500,000,000. The corresponding returns which pay income tax in our country amount to £62\ millions, but this includes only the interest on foreign and colonial securities, coupons, and railways. To this must be added the dividends on miscellaneous industrial undertakings abroad. After all de- ductions on account of other countries which have lent and invested capital with us,^ we ^ " Unfortunately, there are no official figures with regard to the investments of foreigners in this country, though they are certainly III. ON FOREIGN INVESTMENTS 23 may accept the Board of Trade conclusion that " £62\ millions is a minimum figure, which is probably largely exceeded." In 1898, Sir Robert Giffen estimated it at £(^Q millions, and probably more,^ It will be noticed that, while the Invisible Exports should be added to the statistical exports, the income from capital invested abroad takes shape as, and accounts for, a permanent excess of Imports. In other words, if from this moment we stopped lending and investing abroad, we should still receive, year after year, till the capital was repaid, some £60 to ^90 millions worth of value, and most of that value would be embodied in goods. It is not quite correct to say that this repre- sents an import against which there is no export. In many cases, there may have been an export of goods, at the time when the loan was made, to the full amount of the loan, as, for instance, when a colonial government borrows to build a railway, and gets the rails and rolling stock from England. It may, on the other hand, represent no sending of goods at all. If India wants to borrow another million from us, and is owing us ;^i8 very much smaller in the aggregate than British investments abroad. America is the only foreign country, so far as known, whichh as made important investments in the United Kingdom in recent years," Board of Trcuie Blue Book, p. 102. On this whole subject, the admirable article in the Blue Book should be referred to. '^ Royal Statistical Society's Journal, March, 1899. Giffen's calcu- lation, however, includes Pensions, etc., from India and other countries to civil servants living here, of which the Board of Trade says nothing. 24 BOARDING EXPENSES chap. millions a year as it is, all she has to do is to lay hands on a million's worth of goods that otherwise would have come home to us as imports, and keep them — in which case the loan would take shape as a diminution of imports into this country. The point to emphasise is that, in any case, the contracting of the debt, or the investment of the capital, is in the past. But the obligation to pay the interest is a permanent obligation to export a stream of value from foreign countries to our shores as imports. Here, again, one may question the exactness of the figures. But if Great Britain has sent out capital to other countries and these countries have not sent a corresponding amount of capital to it, it seems undeniable that there must be a permanent excess of imports into Great Britain to pay the interest. IV. There is another class of Imports which stands on the same line with the returns from capital invested abroad. It has been happily called " Boarding Expenses " — values sent from one country to another, not to sell or invest, but to consume. This is not a small item. Italy has been credited with i^ 14,000,000, and Switzerland with ;^8,ooo,ooo spent by sightseers. Americans are said to spend some ;^20,ooo,ooo a year in foreign travel. How much of such boarding ex- penses comes to this country, it is impossible to say, but it must be very large. London is the centre of the world, where everybody who can III. PAID IN IMPORTS 25 afford it goes once in a lifetime at any rate. Our own Highland hotels get a considerable share. This category includes remittances sent home to families and schools in England by Civil Servants and military men abroad, furlough expenses, and the like ; and under it, perhaps, fall professional earnings of Englishmen temporarily abroad, such as the gains of theatrical and concert companies on tour. These all represent imports against which there is no corresponding export.^ It must, however, be remembered that large sums are sent abroad by us to other countries for similar pur- poses, and, as Englishmen travel perhaps more than any other nation, the imports on this account may not very greatly overbalance the exports. ^ At the rislc of being tedious, I may repeat here that such board- ing expenses involve sending of goods to pay for any balance there may be between countries. All the traveller knows, of course, is that he takes with hiin, say, circular notes, and, on presenting these, gets money of the country handed over to him. But, suppose that English tourists, in the course of a year, have cashed ;f 100,000 of circular notes in Rome, and that Italian travellers have cashed ;^ 50,000 of their circular notes in London, the Italian and English bankers have simply honoured each other's promises. England is now in debt to Italy to the amount of £\oo,ooo, and Italy is in debt to England to the amount of ^{^50,000. The two sets of promises are set against each other, but there remains a sum of value of ;i{^5o,ooo due to Italian bankers. How is this to be paid ? If the London bankers send drafts on London, this only gives the Italian bankers a claim on gold in London — promises to pay gold there. Even a Bank of England note is, after all, only a promise to pay gold on presentation of the note at the Bank. Some time or other, unless London is to run deeper and deeper in debt to Italy, the accounts must be squared. But, as has been demonstrated, it is usually more convenient to send Bills of Exchange than gold — that is, to give claims on goods sent to Italy in the ordinary course of business — in which case the real payment of the balance is in goods. 26 SMALLER LTEMS chap. Smaller or more occasional items are : {a) The price of old ships sold on the high seas. It is well known that we are continually selling our ships and replacing them with new ones, and these ships do not appear as exports.^ {b) Profits which accrue from capital that was neither lent nor invested abroad, but is yet owned. There are many businesses, or branches of busi- nesses, which have grown up from small beginnings into dividend-paying concerns. Many English- men, again, own land in foreign countries which may have risen indefinitely in value owing to growth of population or the finding of minerals, etc. {c) Gifts, Charities, and Subscriptions, such as the sums sent home from Irishmen in the United States. All these go to swell the stream of imports against which there is no, or practically no, cor- responding export. Together, they must run into many millions. The summing up, then, is this : Our Statistical Imports are ;^5 28,000,000. Our Statistical Exports are ^^^349,000,000 ; to which fall . to be added, at least, another ;^90,ooo,ooo of Invisible Exports of shipping ; making a total of ;^43 9,000,000. This leaves a Balance of Imports of ^^89,000,000. But it has ^ It should be noted, in comparing exports of past years with present figures, that new ships, sold from this country, were not included among our exports before the year 1899, and are properly excluded in comparisons with years before that date. III. PROBABLE BALANCE OF EXPORTS 27 been shown that what we should expect is from ;^6o,ooo,ooo to ^^90,000,000 of annual imports from capital lent and invested abroad, not balanced by any annual exports. All this is to leave out of account the many millions of imports which we receive as Bankers' and other Commissions, as Boarding Expenses, and from the smaller items just mentioned. The probability, in fact, is that our real Balance of Trade is the other way about from what it is usually considered to be ; that it is a Balance of Exports. The excess may be accounted for by the fact that a good deal of interest and profit never comes home, but is invested as capital in the countries where it is made.^ In all this, certainly, there is nothing to shake our faith in the deductive conclusion that, given the exceptions and disturbances noted above, Imports and E^^ports tend to balance each other. 1 Compare the calculation of the French balance by Professor Gide : "As regards France, if, on the one hand, we put to her debit 4500 million francs of imports, 360 millions for carriage of that part of her merchandise which sails under a foreign flag, some hundreds of millions (say 500) for Frenchmen travelling abroad, or against French property held by foreigners — in all, 5400 million francs : and if, on the other hand, we put to her credit 4000 million francs of exports, 1 100 millions as interest on capital lent or invested abroad, 600 millions for expenses of foreigners living in France — in all 5770 million francs ; we see that not only is the required equivalence restored, but that there should remain a considerable surplus to her credit." — Principes d' Economic Politique, 8th edition (1903), p. 283. See also Giffen's remarks on the Balance of other countries : Royal Statistical Society's Jotirnnl, March, 1899, p. 12. CHAPTER IV. THE EQUIVALENCE OF IMPORTS AND EXPORTS. The equivalence we should expect is equivalence simply bctiveen a country's total imports from, and its total exports to, the rest of the world. Imports call out a return current of exports, and exports of imports, through the rise or fall of (i) the foreign exchanges, (2) the freights. But paymeitt is made in very roundabout ways ; not necessarily in imports from the country to which exports are sent, but _/)'^\\ millions in 1891, and £62^ millions in 1901 — over 100 per cent, increase in twenty years. With these figures before us, it seems as if we might rest satisfied that we are not selling out our foreign securities at any rate. II. The second deduction is, that the Balance 40 THE BALANCE INDICATES CHAP. of Trade tells us almost nothing as to the pro- sperity or adversity of a nation. Our own Balance indicates two things. One is that several of our greatest trades, such as Shipping, Banking, and Insurance, are engaged in producing and sending abroad goods that never take any material form, and are not entered in any table of exports. The returns to these trades come to us in imports, and make up an appa- rent excess of something over ;^90,ooo,ooo, the reason being that the real exports which balance and pay for them are not counted at all. The other is that we have for long been the money lenders of the world, and that we have invested very large sums abroad. This accounts for a permanent excess of imports of some ;^6o,ooo,ooo to ^90,000,000. The presumption, of course, is that these trades are prosperous — the Income Tax returns seem to show that they are — and that the interest and profits represent a fair return to our capital abroad. But, from the Balance of Trade, all we know for certain is the two facts, that we have these large trades, and that we have large investments abroad. But another country, from choice or necessity, may not number Shipping among its industries, and yet be employing all its labour and capital profitably. And it may not only find a remunera- tive use for all its savings at home, but may find it cheaper to borrow largely from other countries, getting a better return from the using of the capital borrowed than another country gets V. NEITHER PROGRESS NOR DECAY 41 by lending it — just as one sometimes finds a very rich man borrowing from a very poor re- lation. As consequence of this, such a country may have a balance the other way about. No one now-a-days thinks that America is any the less prosperous that, in 1902, she had a Balance of Exports of ;i^ 100,000,000. If this be true, it follows that even a posi- tive fall- in our exports might indicate nothing but a change in our industries or in our fields of investment — just as, in the converse case, America seems no less prosperous that, this year, her imports show a large increase and her ex- ports a considerable diminution. One is disposed to think that the enormious activity in our Municipal enterprises of late years, and the ease with which such local bodies have borrowed huge sums, would have some effect in putting the drag on our exports. And yet it is by no means certain that Municipal industries may not be as profitable as gold mines. But if anyone still thinks that an excess of imports is a proof of growing decay, let him consider this. We have statistical records, more or less accurate, of the exports and imports of all the great nations. The total imports of these nations are ;^2, 5 16,000,000 ; their total exports are ;^2, 292,000,000. Here is a " debit balance," a balance of imports over exports of ii^2 24,000,000. Either it must be believed that more goods arrive in port than ever set sail, which seems a little curious ; or that all the great nations are going downhill at a very rapid rate — for the balance is 42 WHATEVER CHECKS IMPORTS chap. growing ; or the Board of Trade explanation must be taken, that the balance is accounted for by shipping charges ; — that is, costs incurred after the goods have left any shore as statistical exports. The practical warning conveyed by the ten- dency towards equivalence of exports and imports seems to stare us in the face. It is that anything which checks imports is a check to exports. This follows inevitably from the fact that foreign trade is an exchange of goods and services, goods sent out paying for goods brought in, A tariff not only shuts out foreign goods ; it shuts in home goods. If we were to set up absolutely prohibi- tive tariffs against imports, we should make it impossible to export. For, if the consignee in the foreign country found that, since no goods had been sent to England, he could not buy a bill to cover his remittance, he would send gold. If this were to continue on any large scale, the export of gold from the foreign country would be reflected there in a fall of prices — the prices of imported goods among others. As the only object of exporting goods is to sell them, the low prices realised by our exports would make further exporting on our part unprofitable. If, again, we were to set up tariffs which did not exclude foreign goods but made them dear, we should diminish the consumption of and so the demand for them, and reduce the amount of the exports which we could send in return. If, in these circumstances, we still exported goods in CHECKS EXPORTS 43 the former amounts, the consignee in the foreign country would find that there was a premium on the means of remittance, which would make the transaction pro tanto less profitable, and act as a check on our further exports.^ These things are not less real because they are unseen — hidden by the fact that, in foreign trade, each transaction of exporting and importing stands by itself, and ends with a payment in money. Only those who do not see, or who choose to ignore, any mutual and causal relation between imports and exports, can believe that putting a tariff on imports will have no effect in checking exports. This is the meaning of the ^This is amply confirmed by experience. When Peel, in 1842, took off or reduced duties on over a hundred articles, the exports rose from £a,'o millions to £(iQ millions in 1845. When the Corn Laws were repealed, the exports rose from ^60 millions to nearly ;^IOO millions in 1853. In the late tariff wars, exports suffered correspondingly with imports. See Cd. 1938 : Commercial, No. I. {1904). "Every time," says Gide, "that a treaty of com- merce or any other cause has considerably increased a country's imports, its exports have never failed to increase in like pro- portion. Thus when, in i860, France threw open her ports to foreign products, her imports rose from 2,521,000,000 francs (the average of the previous five years) to 3,231,000,000 francs (the average of the next five years) ; but her exports like- wise rose, between the one period and the other, from 2,813,000,000 francs to 3,449,000,000 francs. Thus the increase in imports was 23 per cent., in exports, 28 per cent." On the whole question, the chapters on International Trade, in Professor Gide's Principes d^ Economic Politique, as the utterances of a French economist, are particularly interesting and suggestive. The above quotation is from the 3rd edition, p. 261, but, as very considerable changes have been made, the 8th edition (Larose, Paris, 1903) should be studied. 44 LOOK AFTER THE IMPORTS CH. v. homely adage : — " Look after the imports and the exports will look after themselves." It simply suggests that, if no restrictions are put on imports, there will be competition from all nations to send in what goods they can, and the necessity of paying for them will bring out a return flow of exports to the same value. CHAPTER VL THE RIVAL POLICIES. Every nation needs a revenue, and so levies customs duties. But, while a Free Trade country has in this no object ulterior to revenue, a protected country has. Apart from political considerations, which, in many cases, determine fiscal policy, the protectionist argument is^ based on the assumption that the interests of the producer are not the same as those of the consumer, and come first. The difficulty of defining Free Trade seems very- much due to this ; that the word " free " is itself so entirely ambiguous. Freedom, as a philosophical conception and as a practical thing, never means the absence of restraint. It is not opposed to Law or Morality. It means putting ourselves under con- scious and purposed restraint — the drunkard who drinks as much as he likes is the very last man we should call " free." For this reason, internal trade is never free in the sense of having no restrictions placed on it. We are a Free Trade country, but we keep as sharp an eye on the manufacture and sale of liquors as any other nation does on their entry : there is no freedom to purvey these as we like. This reminder gives us the cue to a definition. 46 TAXATION FOR REVENUE CHAP. Every nation needs a revenue for national purposes. A Free Trade country is one which imposes duties on imports with no other con- sideration than that of revenue. This comes out quite clearly in the case of spirits and beer. We make them pay Customs duties when they come from abroad, whether from other nations or from our own Colonies ; but any idea that we make them pay because they come from abroad is at once dissipated by the knowledge that we put similar and equivalent duties on spirits and beer made at home, calling the duty, in this latter case, Excise. A distillery or a brewery, in fact, is a kind of island on a lake. We do not allow their products to be imported from them into the surrounding country, without paying the same amount of duty as is paid on similar products coming from countries which are really outside. The actual figures suggest the extent and intention of this government interference. We raise by Customs on foreign beer and spirits, at the gateways of our island, £a^\ millions. But we raise by Excise on our own distilleries and breweries no less than £'^ i \ millions. These two things hang together. It is for the purpose of taxation that we put a duty on home spirits and beer, and we put a similar duty on imported spirits and beer that the foreign articles may not be favoured. Thus the sole explanation of this Customs duty is Taxation : not taxation of the foreigner, not a price for admission, but taxation of the home consumer. In our country, then, we have Import Duties, VI. TAXATION WITH ULTERIOR AIM 47 and heavy import duties, but there is not a shadow of anything ulterior to revenue purposes. It is pure and simple taxation, imposed, as it should be, on ourselves by ourselves, — the special mark of a free nation. What, on the other hand, we call a Protected country is one that frames its Customs duties with an aim ulterior to simple taxation of its own citizens. It does not object to the revenue, but the revenue is not its sole purpose, nor even its main purpose. How such a system works out may be understood if one notices what would happen if we imposed duties on spirits and beer from abroad, and imposed no excise at home. Whatever the object of this might be, it is evident that it would handicap foreign imports and favour the home distiller and brewer. These, then, are the rival policies which we are asked to set against each other. Free Trade, it may be said at once, is the econo- mist's policy. From his point of view, it seems as if there were no question between Protection and Free Trade. He looks on men as wealth pro- ducers and wealth consumers. To g-et the largest amount of wealth-production with the least amount of human exertion, the greater the division of labour the better. He would like the boundary walls of empires broken down entirely as regards trade and industry, and the division of labour made territorial. Whether goods come from Ire- land or from France, is to him the same, so long as they are good and abundant. The whole 48 THIS DEAR DEAR LAND chap. world of man ought to be a vast co-operation of industrial servants, and all hindrances to this co-operation should be removed. So far as pure economic theory goes — and putting aside consider- ations of revenue — customs, excise, duties, tolls, octrois, are remainders of the dark ages. . For all these things cause friction and expense, and the resources of the world, are not fully -exploited. It looks almost' as foolish to im'pose a tariff at Calais and Hamburg, as it would be to tax goods passing through Berwick-on-Tweed. All the same, I am inclined to accuse English economists of being too economic. I think they forget that it suits us to put economic interests first, and the rest nowhere ; they forget how peculiarly favoured we are as compared with most other countries. Shakespeare put it long ago, in words that ring through us like the blast of a trumpet : " This royal throne of kings, this sceptred isle, This fortress, built by nature for herself Against infection and the hand of war ; This happy breed of men, this Httle world, This precious stone set in the silver sea Which serves it in the office of a wall, Or as a moat defensive to a house Against the envy of less happier lands j This blessed plot, this earth, this realm, this England This land of such dear souls, this dear, dear land Dear for her reputation thro' the world — England, bound in with the triumphant sea."' ^ King Richard II. VI. THE POLITICAL CONSIDERATION 49 But the very words which emphasise our insular strength also bring out how peculiar our position is among nations. Between us and attack lies the silver sea — a wall or moat defensive of our house. We have no Alsace and Lorraine to atone for. Our boundary is not a river across which one may throw a stone, like the Rhine, crossed and re- crossed in the past by invading armies. We are not like an old Hanse town, set in a plain, within whose walls we might be shut up, and forced to grow our food in the city streets and make our arms in the city smithies. Our little island is what Venice and Holland were a few centuries ago — a country too small to have many internal resources, but seated, like a spider in its web, at the cross roads which lead to and from the great world. Thus it is that, secure against invasion and the hand of war, our island life is more purely eco- nomic than that of any continental country. Hence, perhaps, the angry jibe of Napoleon at the " nation of shopkeepers " — a very poor jibe, as the Parisian is notoriously the very type of shopkeeper. It annoyed him that we, and we alone, of European nations, could give most of our time and energies to industry. No conti- nental economist, I imagine, would hesitate to say that Free Trade is the policy for us, and that nothing but Free Trade would have given us the position we hold. But Frenchmen and Germans are like Nehe- miah's men ; they have still to hold the trowel in one hand and the sword in the other. The D so THE POLITICAL CONSIDERATION CHAP. atmosphere of two centuries ago is still around them. Wars, in which they personally take part — and not by a shilling a day deputies — keep alive a narrowed national and patriotic life which is strange to us. To guard it, they have to sacrifice — not, like us, in pocket only, but in time, in ease, and sometimes in blood. This is the defence and explanation of the fact that continental economists are, many of them. Protectionists. They aim at making their countries self-sufficient first and rich afterwards. They are not willing to depend too much on nations that might some day encircle them with fire. And so we might imagine that our economic policy of Free Trade is the " natural " policy — the policy to which they have yet to come when the barbarism of war disappears. Here, however, we come right against the fact that there is a country where economic pursuits are even more absorbing than with us ; a country with no army to speak of; with absolutely no foreign question except what she brings on her- self; perfectly secure against attack or invasion ; and that in it Protection has reached its highest point. The country in question is, of course, the United States. Evidently we must find another explanation of Protection beyond the political point of view. There is an explanation, which, if not economic, is at least based on an economic consideration. It is that the continued existence of a nation, as a nation, depends on its finding employment for its own people. VI. PRODUCER VERSUS CONSUMER 51 The Protectionist finds that the world of man is divided into two categories, although the people who occupy these categories are pretty much the same, Consumers and Producers. As a consumer, everybody's anxiety is to get things plentiful and cheap ; and there is no difficulty so long as he has plenty of money in his pocket to buy with. But the only way in which, as a rule, he can get the money is ^by industry. Thus industry comes first. Although the producers, numerically, are a smaller body, they are, economically, more im- portant. Give a man plenty of work and he will have the money. Here seems a plausible case: that the interests of the consumer are selfish, short-sighted, tending to national disintegration. It is especially plaus- ible in the ears of the working man. " The rich are those who have the means of benefiting by cheap goods. The poor — well, there is a previous process with them before they get any goods at all, cheap or dear." Therefore, it is said, the attention of government must be directed to pro- tecting the interests of the producer qua producer. One part of the argument certainly appeals to the economist. He could wish that every man had so much capital at his back as not to be dependent altogether for his daily bread on his daily work. As things are, however, the great majority of the nation have nothing to earn money with but their two hands. Continuous, steady employment, then, is certainly a much more important thing than a halfpenny off the loaf. . 52 STEADY EMPLOYMENT CH. vi. It is a common idea that economists underrate the importance of steady employment. Only very ignorant people can think so. What can be worse than intermittent work, if the object of work be the increasing of the wealth that sup- ports and satisfies life ? What can be worse for the skill and habits of industry than days spent out of work ? Nay — although it is often said that the economist has nothing to do with any but material things — what can be worse for moral beings than compulsory idleness ? I confess I have never been able to find a satisfactory place in economic theory for the Non-Worker. Cer- tainly he has no place in God's universe. He is not even a sponge — for one can wash with a sponge. Work — independent of its product, but necessitated by its product — is the education in which, and only in which, we become men. In idleness alone, as Carlyle said, is there Eternal Despair. Prove, then, that Protection will permanently give the people of this nation fuller employment at the same rate of real wages, or more continuous employment even at a slightly lower rate of wages — to say nothing of higher rates of wages — and we economists will at least reconsider the ques- tion. But what we must ask is, first, to be assured that producers need the help of government, and, second, that government can give this help. This is what we are inclined to deny. CHAPTER VII. PROTECTION. P>-otcction is protection against competition from outside. It does not say that home producers must for ever be subsidised. It uses generally the Itifant Industry argument, which mighty indeed, have some weight if it were not for the notorious fact that these infants never groiv up. What does grow Jip is the Vested Interest, against which nothing short of an economic revolution seems strong enough to prevail. One may very well deprecate the word Pro- tection. It seems to assume that industry can be put under the government as the citizen is put under police — that is, under a power which can protect honest people against those who woulcj do them harm. But the Protection with which we are dealing , is not protection against evil doers: in spite of the militant expressions of many of its advocates, the foreigner who sends us cheap goods is not an evil doer. It is protection against Competition from outside, and therefore from Service from outside. It always seems to me remarkably like that kind of protection which closes the entries of village sports against the, presumably, stronger 54 PROTECTION AGAINST CHEAPNESS chap. outsider, and so secures the prizes — raised by subscription from the countryside, of course — to the villagers. And, being protection against com- petition, it is protection against Cheapness — protection against Abundance. Other nations want to send in their goods at what we may, roughly, call " cost price " — mean- ing cost plus carriage. The protected country says, " No, you shall not, because our people can- not produce so cheaply even when the ' natural protection ' of distance is taken into account ; they must not be undersold ; they must be allowed to sell at their cost price." That is to say, the home consumer must pay a higher price in order to let the home producer sell his goods at all. For, if the protected country could make as cheaply or more cheaply, the argument for Protection would disappear. The rationale of the matter comes out in the absurd provision of the United States, that " works of art by American artists temporarily residing abroad are admitted free ; all other works of art, including paintings, pastels, pen and ink drawings, and statuary, pay a duty of 20 per cent." American artists, evidently, are regarded by their government as tradesmen. No wicked nonsense of Art for Art's sake there. If Americans will buy pictures from Italy and France — well, they must pay for passing by their own countrymen. It is a very good illustration of the contagion of Protection : if a people, with government funds and powers, protect one industry, they must protect all, even the professions ! VII. HOW PROTECTION PROTECTS 55 How, then, does Protection protect ? 1 Let us suppose that, in England and America, the cost price of equal goods is lOOs. And, for 1 clearness sake, let us disregard the additional cost of ocean carriage. America puts on a tariff of 50 per cent. English goods, then, would require to be sold in America for 150s. At these prices, if the American goods are of equal quality, the English goods will not be sold at all. In this case, American producers find that \^ they have the monopoly of their own market, and it would be remarkable if they did not take advantage of it to raise their prices. So long as they can get something under i 50s., they keep the English goods shut out and that is all they want. This is certainly protection of American producers. But the ques- tion, of course, is, Where, in this case, is the need of Protection? If there were no tariff, the ; American would sell at lOOs. and have his profit. Why penalise the American consumer to give the American producer an extra profit ? Take another extreme case. Suppose that the English cost price is lOOs. and the American cost price 200s. Then the English goods sell in America at 150s. The result, of course, is that the Americans cannot sell at all. The Ameri- can consumer gets his goods cheap enough, but there is no American manufacture. Take, lastly, the more likely case, that the English cost is lOOs. and the American cost I 50s. Then the English goods come in on an equal footing of competition with the American goods. The American consumer has, indeed, to 56 INFANT INDUSTRY ARGUMENT chap. pay 50 per cent, more for his goods than he need have paid if he had taken them all from England, but the American manufacturer has his profit, and his industry is " protected." Of course it would not appeal to anybody, if the claim were baldly put forward that a country must, permanently, pay a half more for its goods than it need pay, in order that certain home manufacturers may get a living. The nation would naturally ask, " Cannot we get on without these manufacturers ; are there not other industries that do not need such a costly poor- rate ; would it not be wise to devote our labour and capital to these, taking the cheap goods from abroad with thanks ? " And, certainly, a nation like America, which sends us every year some £121 millions, mostly the produce of her magnifi- cent natural resources, would know that she had plenty of industries which need no protection, and that the exported products of these industries would pay for all the imports she wanted. ; But this bare-faced claim, of home producers to live permanently at the expense of home con- sumers, is not put forward. What is put forward is an argument that appeals to everyone on the face of it, and has even met with some counten- ance from economists, the Infant Industry argu- ( ment.^ Here Protection is defended as a kind ^ This argument, unanimously adopted by American protectionists on the appearance of Alexander Hamilton's famous Report on Manufactures in 1791, was elaborated by Friedrich List in his National System of Political Economy, published 1841. Protec- tion, he said, was a "national apprenticeship"; a stage in a VII. INFANT INDUSTRY ARGUMENT 57 of Patent Law privilege, or Copyright for a certain limited period ; or, to use a favourite metaphor, a kind of apprenticeship, during which the apprentice simply spoils things, and cannot earn a wage. It is the contention, not so much that manufactures are profitable /^r se, as that a varied industry is necessary to a nation's continuous growth, just as a varied diet is. Free Trade, it is said, would condemn a young country too long to mere exploitation of its natural re- sources, to the neglect of industries for which the country is naturally fitted, or is, at least, under no disadvantage : these industries are pre- vented from rising by this exclusive attention to what is easiest, or by some artificial or removable cause. Cotton spinning and weaving in America are cases in point. It seems most natural that they should be carried on where the raw material grows, and where power and coal are abundant. But how are these industries to arise among a population bred in agriculture, unskilled in machinery, unaccustomed to an indoor life, unless steps are taken to protect them in their first stages ? nation's progress, not its final form. List is oflen quoted as an out-and-out Protectionist. He was nothing of the kind. He said, for instance, that the maintenance of Protection in England at the time he wrote was a mistake due to the stupidity of the ruling class. Going over the history of the great nations, he showed that they had all had this period of apprenticeship : first, Free Trade in the agricultural stage, when there were no separate manufactures on a great scale ; then Protection ; last, he said, should come Free Trade. The same ideas, and the same moderation, are found in Alexander Hamilton. 58 /. S. MILL CHAP. The argument is very plausible. Owing to the progress of science and invention, quick and cheap transit, the mobility of capital and of highly skilled men, Mill's words are much more true now than when they were written, that " the superiority of one country over another in a branch of production often arises only from having begun it sooner," and that a country which can get I or hire skill and experience may, in other respects, \ be better adapted to the production than those ) which were earlier in the field. I am not, how- \ever, going to contest Mill's statement that "a /protecting duty, continued for a reasonable time, will sometimes be the least inconvenient mode in which the nation can tax itself for the support of such an experiment," ^ because it has no bearing on our present problem, ^This concession of Mill has so often been torn from its con- ) text and used to support doctrines which he would have abhorred, that it is advisable to quote the next sentence : ' ' But the protection should be confined to cases in which there is good ground of assurance that the industry which it fosters will, after a time, be able to dispense with it ; nor should the domestic producers ever be allowed to expect that it will be continued to them beyond the time necessary for a fair trial of what they are capable of accomplishing." — Principles of Political Economy, v. x., i. One may read along with this Sidgwick's statement : " I hold that, when the matter is considered from the point of view of abstract theory, it is easy to show that Protection, under certain not im- probable circumstances, would yield a direct economic gain to the protecting country ; but that, from the difficulty of securing in any actual government sufficient wisdom, strength, and singleness of aim to introduce protection only so far as it is advantageous to the community, and withdraw it inexorably so soon as the public interests require its withdrawal, it is practically best for a states- man to adhere to the broad and simple rule of taxation for revenue VII. A DIVERSIFIED INDUSTRY 59 I consider it fallacious to say that Protection is necessary for the rise of a diversified industry. Industries would naturally take root in an agri- cultural country by the growth of what one might call the supplementary industries ; beginning with the jobbing and repairing trades that merely put things together, and make things that cannot be imported — just as the smith and the joiner set up repairing sheds in country districts, and are found ere long to be taking contracts for making and building.^ But the argument has no applica- tion to us. If we are going to adopt Protection, it will certainly not be because our industries are infants. And, as it happens, this is exactly where the argument breaks down as regards America. only." — Principles of Political Economy, book iii., chap. v. It may be said that we, in this country, have statesmen with such wisdom, strength, and singleness of aim. But how long should we have them if they were exposed to the influences which attend Protection ? ^ What is meant may be illustrated from the history of Barrow- in-Furness. Fifty years ago it was a sandhill. Then hematite ore deposits were discovered, and steel-making settled down beside the raw material. Next came shipbuilding to take advantage of the steel. Clustered round this are now all manner of subsidiary industries, making machinery and other auxiliaries for shipbuilding and steel-making, and the prosperity of the town is no longer dependent on any one industry. Or take the familiar pheno- menon of the overflow of capital in South Africa from the gold mines to coal fields, water supplies, machinery making, etc. Does any one think that the working out of the gold mines would leave nothing but a few holes in the ground ? Has not, indeed, gold- mining set many communities on their feet, and left them with the " varied industry" desiderated? 6o ONCE INFANT, ALWAYS INFANT chap. The suggestion is that manufacture, in a new country, is a child which requires to be protected against winter and rough weather, till such time as it is fuller grown and is able to take its place in the competition of nations. Unfortunately, experience shows us that this time never arrives. Once an infant, always an infant. Sir Charles Tupper declared long ago that, given fifteen years of Protection, the infant industries of Canada would be able to stand alone. The fifteen years are gone ; twenty-five years are gone. The infants are still in arms. So with America, whose favourite argument this still is, even as regards that Mellin's Food baby, the Steel Trust. Practically, all industries there are protected. We must conclude, then, either that all the industries are yet in their infancy — and a century is a long time for long clothes — or else we commit ourselves to some theory of permanent infancy. When the question, then, is put — as it should be put — why America is still protectionist, the answer may be given in a sentence. It is the strength of the Vested Interest. It is not sufficiently remembered that, while Free Trade may be called the " natural " policy, inasmuch as it applies to foreign trade the policy and principles which we find every country adopt- ing in its home trade, it is not the historical policy. It is only since the Reformation that the idea of the Nation-State began to evolve. The Nation then became an entity — a whole, which Vii. PROTECTION ONCE UNIVERSAL 6i it was worth any sacrifice to hold together, and inspire with a common purpose. Naturally, for some centuries, the course of evolution was that each nation became an object of jealousy, sus- picion, and dislike to other nations. When Colbert, Louis XIV.'s great Minister, established a heavy tariff against all other countries, he did indeed draw the French nation together. But, at the same time, he accentuated the enmity of other states, and thus, says Adam Smith, " began the. spirit of hostility which has subsisted be- tween the two nations ever since." This policy was followed by every other country, under the pernicious idea that one nation's gain is another nation's loss. Consequently, down till the middle of last century, all nations were shut in by a tariff based on the principle known in Scotland as " keeping their ain fish guts for their ain sea maws." We ourselves were as heavily protected as other countries ; and we had, moreover, enjoyed the very special protection of the twenty years of the Napoleonic war, during which we had freedom to apply the new discoveries and inventions to manufacture, while the rest of Europe was devastated by in- vading armies, and had enough to do to live. The abolition of the Corn Laws in 1846, and the adoption of Free Trade, was an almost revolutionary movement, made possible perhaps by the dread of a bloodier revolution. It was a quick, sharp spasm, like the cut of the surgeon's knife. It introduced the " natural " system at great loss and suffering to some, but it cleared 62 VESTED INTERESTS chap the way for the free development and full use of the great inventions and cheap communication which were changing the face of the world. That is to say, the innumerable vested interests, which had grown up under Protection, were ruth- lessly cut at the root. But in other countries they remained, still remain, and tend to grow stronger the older they grow. I should not like it to be thought that I mention " vested interests " with any contempt, or that the expression carries its own condemna- tion. Most of our interests are vested, in greater or lesser degree. I only take it as a fact of human nature that, when a man's bread and butter is bound up with the continuance of a system, how- ever bad, the vested interest that appeals to him is the interest of the wife and children at home ; and these interests sometimes make him singularly shortsighted as to the real interests of himself and others. In early days, it is said, the joiners in Japan protested against the introduction of the • fire engine, on the ground that it interfered with their industry of rebuilding the wooden houses.^ This seems absurd enough, but it is absurd only because the interest is a small one. But consider this case. Of the 39 millions of population in France, nearly one-half are interested in agricul- ture. Most of them are small peasant proprietors. ' At the end of the eighteenth century, the southern counties of England petitioned Parliament against the opening of the Great North Road, on the ground that it would bring the products of the northern counties into the London market. VII. REQUIRE A REVOLUTION 63 They are the salt of France. But these peasants could not compete with foreign grain introduced free. Free Trade would mean an entire re- organisation of agriculture, and, probably, of the land system. It would be an economic revolution. Here is one vested interest which extends over half a nation, and makes it impossible for any ministry such as France has known for thirty years to even mention the free import of grain. But America never had an economic revolution such as we had. She had no need to protect her agriculture. Hence her people could always get the prime necessaries of life cheap and good. They never knew what it was to have wheat at 80s. — the price which, it was thought, the agricultural interests in this country should have for their own safety ; and they, consequently, never saw rents rising, and one privileged class flourishing, while the people starved. This cheap agricultural produce, moreover, they could export, and with it buy what they wanted of other things. But at an early stage they adopted Protection for their manufactures, and the beginning of it was perfectly natural and explicable. Up till 1808, the nation had remained very much as when it was a number of British colonies — exclusivelyagricultural; importing manu- factures, and paying for them (i) by exports of agricultural produce to the West Indies and to those countries of Europe where the French armies were trampling down the fields, and (2) by the invisible exports of shipping, shipbuilding being then a chief industry of New England. 64 HISTORY OF PROTECTION chap. Then came the Berlin and Milan Decrees of Napoleon, the Embargo, and the Non-Intercourse Act of 1809, followed by the war with England in 1 8 1 2. Practically all foreign trade was stopped, and America thrown on her home resources. This, of course, gave an enormous stimulus to those branches of industry whose produce had before been imported, and the manufacture of jcotton goods, woollen cloth, iron, glass, pottery, and other articles sprang up like mushrooms. 1 When the war was over, there remained, naturally, a feeling in favour of these manu- factures, and higher duties were imposed to give tpem a chance in competition with the English goods which then began to pour in.^ This was ^ " The manufacturers of Great Britain, well knowing the needs of the American markets, made haste to send over their goods, which, in the early summer of 1815, began to arrive in fleets of merchant vessels, in such quantities as had never before been known. Coming over consigned to nobody, the goods were hurried by the super- cargoes and captains in charge of them to the auction block, where, to the surprise of the owners, high prices were obtained by the sharp competition of eager buyers. . . . During April, May, and June, 1 81 5, the duties paid at the New York custom houses on goods, waies, and merchandise brought from England amounted to 3,960,000 dollars. When the news of the quick sales and great profits at auction reached Great Britain, whole fleets of vessels were loaded and despatched to America. One day in November, 1815. twenty square-rigged ships came up the harbour of New York. On another day fifteen ships and eight brigs arrive ; and what went on at New York was repeated at every seaport along the Atlantic coast. The gainers by this unusual trade were the British manufacturers, the British ship-owners, the auctioneers, and the Federal and State treasuries. The sufferers were the American importers, manufac- turers, and wholesale merchants, who without delay appealed to Congress for protection." — Prof. M 'Master in Cambridge Modern History, vol. vii. p. 354. VII. IN AMERICA 65 Strengthened by the shutting out of agricultural produce from England under the Corn Laws. It was, in fact, very much our stringent protective policy which forced America into manufacturing for herself She was not allowed to pay for her imports by agricultural exports. For twenty years from 1 8 16, the protective policy was continuous, and it was based on the Infant Industry argument. By 1830, or perhaps earlier, the "diversified industry" was attained ; the Infant Industry argu- ment lost its force. In 1833, for instance, it was said that the cotton industry was ready and able to meet imports on a free-trade footing. Between that and i860, there was great vacillation in the tariff policy ; high and low tariffs succeeding each other in a very unprincipled way. From i 846, indeed, the country seemed to be approaching Free Trade. Then, unhappily, came again the old spring and excuse of Protection. To raise revenue for carrying on the Civil War which began in i860, every possible article, home and foreign, was taxed, and taxed heavily. The statesmen in power were protectionists, and Protection ran riot. After the war, the removal of internal and excise taxation was not accompanied by removal of the customs tariff. The war tariff of 1864 remained in force for twenty years without reduction. The growing feeling towards Free Trade disappeared. Many industries had grown up, or been greatly extended, under the influence of the war legislation. That some were unsuitable to the country did not appeal to those who had sunk their fortunes in them. The infant industry, crippled from its E 66 PROTECTION IN AMERICA CH. vii. birth, appeared as good a subject for protection as the infant industry that only required benevolent care during its early years.^ And, ever since, the Vested Interest has riveted its hold. What appears, then, in America is the phenomenon of the employers in practically all manufacturing industries crying out, in the name of justice, for equal Protection ; and the workers are easily persuaded that their living depends on the continuance of these industries. At the back of it all are the two facts : that America is a country of such vast natural resources that it would be difficult for any fiscal system to keep back the progress of the nation, and that, within its great area, there is absolute free trade. 1 See passim Taussig's Tariff History of the United States, and Rabbeno's American Commercial Policy, CHAPTER VIII. THE PRINCIPLE OF A PROTECTIVE TARIFF. IVhat principle regulates the differeiitiation of rates in a tariff? Is it prohibition, or equalisation of labour costs, or equalisation of costs generally? Whatever principle be alleged, experience shows that rates are determined by warring interests, either as a victory or as a compromise. So much for the genesis of Protection and its con- tinuance. It does not arise from a thought-out poHcy : the economists are not consulted. During the restriction of a war, a country starts making things for itself, without regard to " natural ad- vantages," or, indeed, to anything but necessity. When the war is over, it is thought that the pro- ducers have deserved well of their countrymen ; the government undertakes to secure them from rapid extinction at the hands of more advanced nations ; and it is only a question of time till the vested interests can neither be overlooked nor silenced.^ 1 This, of course, does not account for the rise of Protection in our self-governing Colonies. Here the explanation is the natural tendency of a tariff for revenue to pass into a tariff" for protec- tion. Every colony, however new, needs a revenue. It is diflicult to 68 PRINCIPLE OF A TARIFF chap. But a tariff is not a simple thing. It is not a uniform rate. It consists of a great range of differential duties, some low, others high, some few prohibitive. And, inevitably, at every revision — and the American tariff has been altered 1 some forty times since 1789 — the question is| raised as to what is the principle of these differ- j ences. I cannot answer this question. It is not as if the protected country drew up a tariff with the object of getting the largest revenue at the least hardship to the consumers. It admits foreign goods of compulsion and unwillingly. A self- sufficient country like the United States, for get it from internal taxation (whether levied directly on income or land, or, levied indirectly, on commodities), on account of the small and scattered population ; and the obvious course is taken of imposing heavy taxes on imports. Behind these import duties, gradually rise vested interests. It is represented, in the usual way, that a " diversified industry " is necessary, and cannot spring up without enough protection to overcome the natural handicaps. The infant industries, once supported by government crutches, never willingly abandon them, and the vested interest does the rest. There is another explanation forcibly put by Fawcett {Free Trade and Protection, p. ii). It is that emigrant artizans have difficulty in finding in a colony the kind of employment to which they have been accustomed. They do not take willingly to the land ; even gold mining is found not always a short cut to wealth. So they naturally favour the establishment by Protection of industries where their old skill can find opportunity. And, in several of our Colonies, "labour legislation," as it is called, is almost alarmingly prominent. While these sheets were passing through the press, the Premier of New South Wales had to point out to a deputation of men unemployed through the cessation of public works that the government did not borrow money merely to find employment for the citizens. VIII. M'KINLEY: ROOSEVELT 69 instance, might be quite content to have no imports. But, as Sumner says, " As soon as we get the home market firmly shut, so that nobody else can get in, we find that it is a question of life and death with us to get out ourselves." ^ And the exports inevitably bring the imports which pay for them. Hence the need of differ- entiating the tariff, so as to admit imports with the least harm to home producers. In such circumstances, a principle is scarcely to be looked for. But I may quote some utterances which seem to admit that the need of a principle is felt — if it be only to make the tariff respectable. President M'Kinley, presented his revised tariff Bill with the following words: "The object of tariff taxation is not the raising of revenue, but, on the contrary, the reduction of revenue, and ultimately the extinction of revenue, by duties to be raised to a height sufficient for the accomplishment of this end." Here is a confession that the aim of Protection is Prohibition. First put on a tariff If foreign goods come in, raise it higher. If they still come in, raise it again, till " revenue is extinguished " ; that is, till no goods come in at all. With more plausibility. President Roosevelt, in the Message to Congress, December, 1901, said: \ " Every application of our tariff policy to meet our shifting national needs must be conditional upon the cardinal fact that the duties must never be reduced below the point that will cover the difference between the labour here and abroad." ^Protectionism, p. SS. / 70 EQUALISATION OF LABOUR COSTS CHAP. This seems to assume that the American labourer has, somehow or other, got his wages up so high that the wages have raised the cost of production of American goods, and that the goods coming from other nations must be taxed to raise them to the same price, or else wages will be brought down. It is the so-called Pauper Labour argu- ment — an argument, by the way, which was used by ourselves in 1779 in regard to Irish labour, when Lord North proposed to allow Ireland to trade with the Colonies and with foreigners on the same footing as England. But it reads very strangely to those who remember that France and Germany urge the need of protection against America for precisely the opposite reason, namely, that American labour is so well paid and productive ! One could understand this if the high wages of America were artificial ; if, for instance, Trade Unionism were there so powerful that wages were raised quite apart from the product of work. But, notoriously, this is not the case. Trade Unionism in America is weak. The high wage is evidently the result — the natural and happy result — of high industrial skill, working with cheap raw material, and fed on abundant food. " This claim for Pro- tection to American industry, founded on the high scale of American remuneration, is a demand for special legislation and in consideration of the possession of special industrial facilities — a com- plaint, in short, against the exceptional bounty of nature."^ If the proposition is read in any other way, ^ Cairnes, Some Leading Principles, p. 385. VIII. EQUALISATION OF COSTS 71 it seems to amount to this : that prices generally in a protected country are high ; living, accord- ingly, is dear; and workers need high wages to pay the high prices. But, as wages are " labour cost," the high prices are assumed to be the result of high wages ! High prices explain high wages, and high wages explain high prices — a very pretty example of circular reasoning. All this is exceedingly crude ; so I turn to a principle suggested by an American economist, for whom we all have a very high respect. Professor J. B. Clark, of Columbia University.^ " It would be entirely reasonable," he says, " to reduce each duty to an amount that equals the difference in cost between the American and the foreign article. Find out accurately how much the owner of an '^ The Control of Trusts: Macmillan, 1901. Economists in America are in rather a difficult position. If they speak in defence of Protection, they lose their scientific reputation. If they speak fearlessly against it, even if they escape being turned out of their Universities, they lose their influence with the people — for Political Economy in America, it has been said, is regarded as the science of tariff regulation. Besides, they have always the consciousness that an industrial system which is protected from head to heel re- quires a revolution to change it, and they have to weigh the advantages of setting industry on a sound economic basis against the gigantic disturbance and loss which would, in the first instance, accrue. "Whatever may be said about the wisdom of having tariffs at all," says Professor Clark, "a country which actually has one, and which under it has built up industries that are still in some degree dependent on it, will be cautious in abolishing it." But they are all tariff reformers ; and, in the present case, Professor Clark, acknowledging that the actual tariff is "irrationally protective," puts forward a principle which, without saying anything for the abolition of Protection, would show that a reduction of tariff' was "entirely reasonable." A 72 y. B. CLARK CHAP. American mill has to spend in the creating of a particular product, ascertain with the same accuracy how much the European spends for the same purpose, and make the duty on the com- pleted article equal to the difference between the two sums. The European can then place his goods on the American market at an outlay which, when duties are paid, equals the outlay in- curred by his American rival. The two will then be more nearly on an equal footing, and success will come to the one who improves his processes more rapidly, and makes the largest savings in the advertising and selling of his wares. The public will get the benefit of this rivalry in economical production, and will get its goods at the maximum of cheapness."^ The principle is, that a tariff should put home producer and foreign producer on a footing of perfect competition ; competition, in Professor Clark's view, being " the regulator of prices and wages, and the general protector of the interests of the public." ^ The idea that a tariff should give any monopoly to the home producer is expressly disclaimed. This is not the place to go into any detailed criticism of the principle thus laid down. It is enough, perhaps, to say that, when Professor Clark says " European," he seems to have been thinking of " British " ; in other words, to have been think- ing of the difference of cost as between a protected and a free-trade country. But other protected nations send their goods into America, and every nation has a different cost. A tariff based on his 1 The Control of Trusts, p. 43. "^ Ibid. Preface, p. v. VIII. THE REAL DETERMINANT 73 principle, then, would seem to involve differential duties against every separate country. And I do not think he has sufficiently considered the diffi- culty of arriving " accurately " at cost in any country except by taking the selling price. Apart from all this, it seems clear that few Protectionists would admit that the end of a tariff is merely to equalise costs and secure competition. They always aim at partial or total monopoly. But one gets tired of seeking for a principle in a tariff where, at each revision, the changes are so obviously determined, not by sober scientific and economic calculation, but by the weight of the influence brought to bear on the politicians.^ In 1882, Congress appointed a Tariff Commission to collect evidence and report. With the exception of one person, it consisted entirely of Protec- tionists. It recommended a reduction of 25 per cent, saying wisely : " Excessive duties are positively injurious to the interests which they are supposed to benefit. They encourage the invest- ment of capital in manufacturing enterprises by rash and unskilled speculators, to be followed by disaster to the adventurers and their employes, and a plethora of commodities which deranges the operation of skilled and prudent enterprise." Its recommendations were simply put aside ; and the new tariff of the next year was " kicked about ^ I once asked a manufacturer in the United States why the duty on his goods was 40 per cent. — not 30 per cent, or 50 per cent. His answer, I fancy, put the truth in a nutshell. "Our Congress- man," he said, "came round and asked, what duty do you want? and we said 40 per cent, would do." 74 WES GUYOT CHAP. in committee till it came out a grotesque com- promise of warring interests." The experience of France is the same. To quote M. Yves Guyot : " Not only does Protec- tionism plunge the country which adopts it into ^ a war of tariffs with all other countries, but, even within the country, it rouses a spirit of antagonism in every district which thinks itself sacrificed to other districts, and in every industry which de- mands to be protected over and above other industries, and at their expense. Under Protec- tion, economic rivalry gives place to political rivalry. This is confirmed by the daily experi- ence of every Protectionist country. I have had special opportunities of seeing how private in- terests combine against the public interest in the French Parliament, The whole art of M. Meline, who has been the Protectionist leader for close on 25 years, has consisted in uniting groups of often contradictory interests, paying court to them, effecting bargains between this and that party, always to the detriment of the consumer, who is the general public. ' Beetroot strikes a bargain with Wine ; Cotton and Iron come to an under- standing.' There, in a nutshell, you have the part which Protection plays in parliamentary life." ^ Lastly, take our own experience. In 1840 a Committee of the House of Commons reported as follows : " The tariff of the United Kingdom presents neither congruity nor unity of purpose. No general principles seem to have been applied. '^ Fortnightly Review, ]\i\yy igo'^. VIII. OUR OWN EXPERIENCE 75 The tariff often aims at incompatible ends ; the duties are sometimes meant to be both productive of revenue and for protection, objects which are frequently inconsistent with each other. Hence they sometimes operate to the complete exclusion of foreign produce, and' in so far no revenue can of course be received ; and sometimes, when the duty is inordinately high, the amount of revenue is, in consequence, trifling. They do not make the receipt of revenue the main consideration, but allow that primary object of fiscal regulations to be thwarted by the attempt to protect a great variety of particular interests at the expense of revenue, and of the commercfal intercourse with other countries. Whilst the tariff has been made subordinate to many small producing interests at home, by the sacrifice of revenue, in order to support their interest, the same principle of inter- ference js largely applied by the various dis- criminating duties, to the produce of our colonies, j by which exclusive advantages are given to the colonial interests at the expense of the mother countr}^" The conclusion seems inevitable ; that, where duties are differentiated with the view of protect- ing, not the industries which should exist but the { industries which do exist, and where the amount of the differentiation is arrived at by a struggle of competing interests and unequal weight of influence, it is useless to look for a principle. ■ / I CHAPTER IX. POSSIBILITY OF A SCIENTIFIC TARIFF. In the framing of a tariff by a country hitherto Free Trade, certain broad principles would be cucepted, but each presents its own diffi- culties, (i) Exotic goods allowed in free wotdd not, indeed, cot)ipete with home industries, but they are the favotirite objects of revenue taxation. (2) Free food conflicts with the interest of the home agri- culturist. (3) Free raw materials conflict, not only with agricul- tural atid mining industries, but with those who use home-produced ra'iv material. But the attempt to define ^^raw" material presetiis endless difficulties. And the importance of cheap raiv materials, as compared with the importance of cheap manufacttired materials^ if these should happen to be the basis of national industries, is not obvious. (4) Taxed manufactures encounte) the latter objection, and, besides, include tools. One begins to see why it is that a country which once adopts Protection ends by taxing every thittg. But even if one is convinced of the impossi- bility of revising a tariff on anything Hke economic principles, when once vested interests have tightened their hold, there may remain a belief that a scientific tariff could be drawn up by a country which had hitherto been Free Trade. Without attempting to define the adjective " scientific," which would, perhaps, prejudge the CH. IX. TAXING EXOTIC GOODS AND FOOD 77 case, let us look at certain deductions of ex- perience as to the taxing of imports. I. Common sense dictates the free admission of things a country cannot grow or make. Dear goods, as dear goods, are bad. If, then, a government, in order to protect certain indus- tries, is going to make many things dear, there is all the more reason that it should let in j non-competing things cheap. But here steps in the Chancellor of the Exchequer. He must have a revenue, and he cannot raise all that revenue by direct taxes. He knows that, in proportion as the protective tariff is successful, there will be little revenue ; if it be completel}' successful, none. Such luxuries, then, as Tea, Tobacco, and Spirits are the things on which he can most easily raise an assured revenue, with a minimum expense of col- lection. So, under a protective tariff like that of Canada, heavy import duties, amounting to an average of 170 per cent., are put on such goods. n. Common sense seems to dictate the free admission of Food. The prosperity of a com- munity surely depends, fundamentally, on getting the animal basis of life as cheap as possible. The human worker is, after all, the great Tool. The argument is strengthened, in our case, by the consideration that many of the countries with which we compete do not require to protect their agriculture. Nature has done it for them. For us to put on such a duty, seems like 78 TAXING FOOD chap. deliberately handicapping ourselves in the inter- national race by raising the cost of production of Man. Hence, up till the present, it was thought that, if there be a form of Protection which would be totally indefensible in this country, it is the taxation of food. But here steps in the agriculturist, and asks, with some heat, if the manufacturing classes are to be favoured, while the oldest industry in the world, and still the largest, is to be left to merciless competition with cheap food from every country under heaven? Indeed, in our case, if there is an argument for the protection of any class of producers, it almost seems as if it should be protection for the producers of food, seeing that we are actually at a natural disadvantage, as compared with many other countries, by reason of our climate and the narrow area of land suitable for each crop. And if there is an industry in the country which has some reason to think meanly of Free Trade, it is Agriculture — remem- bering, always, that the agricultural interest which can and does make itself heard most, is the interest of the landowner. In fact, it was made a special claim for Ireland — in a Royal Commission — that its agriculture was destroyed by Free Trade, and that it never had the manufacturing industries on which to make up the loss. III. If a country has sunk most of its capital I and specialised most of its energies in manufac- ( turing, the free import of raw materials seems IX. TAXING RAW MATERIALS 79 almost necessary. This has generally been re- cognised by the most protectionist countries. There is scarcely room for difference of opinion as to the admission of materials a country cannot produce for itself But, beyond such imports, the free admission of raw materials encounters the opposition of those who raise similar or com- peting raw materials at home, and naturally object to the competition of countries which can raise them more cheaply. At this point arise the most serious conflicts of interest. Wool, for instance, is a raw material of many manufac- tures. But if, to suit the woollen manufacturer, it is admitted free, this comes into rough colli-/ sion with the interests of the farmer — one of his staple products being sheep. Say, however, that wool is not admitted free, then, in many coun- tries, the silk, cotton, and linen manufacturers are favoured ; as using foreign raw material, they get the basis of their industries presumably more cheaply. For it should not be forgotten that woollens do compete in use with cotton and linen and silk. Everyone knows the position which flannelette — a cotton fabric — has taken in the clothing of the poor. In certain shop windows, one sees a strenuous attempt — backed by expert evidence — to prove that linen is a healthier under- wear than wool, while Dr. Jaeger brings his own evidence to prove the contrary. Silk, of course, is an active competitor with wool in the same line, except that it is so expensive. In socks and stockings, again, there is competition between Lisle thread, silk, worsted, and mixtures. So in 8o TAXING RA W MA TERIALS chap. carpets, hangings, table covers, and the like, with the addition here of jute as a serious competitor.^ The endeavour to secure cheap raw material for the manufacturer who employs imported material as his base, and yet to give equal treat- ment to the manufacturer who uses home raw material, becomes almost hopeless where the pro- tected country not only produces the raw material, but works it up. Here the grower clamours for protection and the manufacturer for free admission. One would think that, if there is a raw material which should be admitted free into France, it is silk fibre, silks being, of course, the traditional export of France. Yet, in 1892, the Communes could scarcely resist the agitation for the protection of the home cultivated cocoon, and only escaped it by offering a bribe to the home producers, in the form of a grant of over 3,000,000 francs for primary and technical education in agri- culture.2 Here is another case, difficult to put under a category. It is where two raw materials are necessary for one fabric, and the one material comes from abroad, while the other is produced at ^ In 1902, the Agrarian Party in Austria asked for a duty against raw cotton, with the avowed object of protecting wool and flax. The argument used was : If raw cotton from abroad is admitted free, cotton goods are produced more cheaply than woollen and linen goods, whose raw material is grown at home, and a blow is struck at the farmer and flax grower. ^ Economic /otirnal, September, 1896. IX. TAXING RAW MATERIALS 8i home, Farrer gives an example which might be paralleled, in all probability, from other industries. Everyone knows those mixed cotton and silk fabrics, made in the factories of Lyons. Here cotton yarn is woven along with silk yarn. But cotton yarn is an import heavily taxed in order to protect the cotton spinners of Lille. The Lyons weavers, then, complained that many of their yarns could not be obtained except from Eng- land, and, moreover, that they were suffering competition from Switzerland, where cotton yarns were admitted free. The Lille spinners, on the other hand, urged that " the distress among the Lyons weavers was nothing to that prevail- ing among the Lille spinners." Here it is French spinners against French weavers.^ The fact is, that any particular raw material may be the sole base of one manufacturing in- dustry, or one of the bases, or only a trifling auxiliary ; while it may, at the same time, occupy a different position, as basis or auxiliary, in several competing industries. It is impossible to recon- cile all these interests. But what is a " Raw Material " ? The term is not a scientific one. No definition of it appears in the Dictionary of Political Economy. It is not even a Board of Trade or Custom-house category. ^ The remedy suggested by the President of the Lille Chamber of Commerce shows the ridiculous impasse in which attempts to recon- cile warring interests often land. It was to raise the duty on agri- cultural products, in order that French agriculturists might grow rich and become better purchasers of French manufactures ! — Farrer, Free Trade versus Fair Trade, p. 167. F 82 WHAT IS RAW MATERIAL? chap. Generally, we are left to infer that what does not appear under the category " manufactured," is raw material — so long as it is not " food and drink." According to our official trade accounts, Sawn Timber is not a raw material, which would seem to show that only tree trunks are "raw"; in which case a thing remains raw if an axe is laid upon it, and is manufactured when passed through a saw mill. In the German and French tariffs. Pig-iron is a raw material, excluded from the category of " manufactured " ; with us, and with the United States, it is included. Even Slates and Stones with us are manufactures. In highly protective countries, one has to infer what is counted raw material from the fact of its paying the lowest rate of duty. With us wool, dirty or clean, is considered raw material. But there is a refinement in the American tariff which is very suggestive. Unwashed wools are wools shorn from the sheep's back without any cleansing. Washed wools are wools washed with water only, on the sheep's back or on the skin. Wools washed in any other manner are " scoured." The importance of the subtle distinction comes out in the provision that washed wools pay double the duty of unwashed wools, and that scoured wools pay three times the duty. So that, if a bottle of sheep-dip is put into the water at the washing, it would seem that treble duty is payable, while leaving sheep altogether unwashed allows the wool to get in at the lowest figure — a premium on dirt and disease which, I imagine, would not be IX. TAXING MANUFACTURED MATERIAL 83 without its effects. So far as this goes, it seems to indicate that the difference betvveei " raw material " and " partly manufactured material is a question of soap and water. Thos^ people, then, who speak so glibly about letting in raw material free, have evidently some work before them when they try to determine at what stage any material is " raw," and at what stage it should be taxed. But this is not a mere difficulty of classifica- tion. Even if we could define a raw material with absolute accuracy, the proposal to admit it free, while taxing all other " material," is exceed- ingly serious. What affects the home producer is not in the least whether the material he buys is really " raw " or something very far from being raw. The thing that affects him, and his trade, is that the material with which he starts should be cheap. Why is it that the non-taxation of raw material appeals to everybody as reasonable? Is it not that it is the interest of the producer, of the consumer, and of the exporter, that goods should cost as little as possible? If the raw material accounts for a large part of the selling price of the manufacture, and we tax that mate- rial, we make the finished article proportionally dear. But if our national manufactures happen to begin with a material which is not " raw," but has already passed through some processes of pre- paration before it comes here, is not the hurt of import duties to these industries — their producers, consumers, and exporters — exactly the same as if we taxed the raw material? Can anyone say 84 TAXING MANUFACTURED MATERIAL chap. why our manufacturers should begin with the so-called raw material, or be penalised because they do not? Is it not as profitable perhaps to begin with material already partly manufac- tured ? It is quite clear that, in home trade, the manu- factured product of one industry becomes the material and substance of another. Our weavers do not spin ; they buy yarn from the spinners and weave it. The tailor begins with the cloth. The watchmaker begins with a whole complex of ready- made components. Why should it be made a misfortune that the first — and, presumably, less skilled — process of manufacture should not be done in this country? Is it a misfortune that our silk manufacturers begin with silk that has already passed through several stages ; that our cycle makers begin with a few components bought from America ; that our joiners do not begin with tree trunks, but with sawn timber, or even with ready-made doors and window sashes? Is not the taxation of partly manu- factured materials in flat contradiction to all we have been taught, since Adam Smith, of the advantages of the division of labour?^ The only ground I can find for the belief that raw material should be admitted free, as compared ^As regards the Brewing trade, it has been pointed out that staves come from Norway, hoops from Holland, capsules from Germany, casks from Sweden, hops and grain from various countries: that, as a matter of fact, all this country contributes in the way of raw material is the water used in the manufacture, and the straw for packing. But brewing is one of our staple British industries. IX. FOOD AND RAW MATERIAL 85 with everything which has passed through a pro- cess, is the ineradicable belief of some people that we ought to do everything ourselves ; and that, if an article passes through six stages before it comes out a finished good for consumption, we are somehow defrauded if we do not secure more than five of them. It seems to me almost as absurd as insisting that we teachers should read nothing but English books, or, perhaps, should write our own books. One would think these are difficulties enough, but I should like to note one more. It is that of distinguishing between Food and raw material. For, as it happens, imported food is the raw material of much of our new agriculture. It is said, indeed, that the salvation of modern farming has come from the possibility of getting cheap feeding for cattle. Mr. Balfour put this strongly, in May of 1903, when defending the abolition of the tax on grain. " Let me ask farmers," he said, " if they really think that, from the point of view of feeding stuffs, the tax is really to their advantage? ... I maintain that the tax has operated as a burden on the raw viaterial used by farmers!' Flour, again, is a Food. But is it not also the raw material of several things we undoubtedly call manufactures ? Maize is the substance of corn-flour, and corn-flour is a food ; but the spoiled corn-flour goes into starch, and starch is a manufacture. If, again, meat is taxed as food, is this not a tax on leather, the raw material of many industries ? 86 TAXING MANUFACTURES chap. IV. The only class of goods remaining for con- i' sideration, after foreign products that we cannot make, food, and raw materials, is what we call Manufactures. And generally, ever since the days of Colbert, the opinion of rising countries is \ that the import of manufactures should be pro- hibited or handicapped wherever they interfere with or threaten similar home manufactures. Manufactured commodities, it is assumed, are the goal of industry. It is in order to manufacture them cheaply that we admit food and raw material free. If we allow free entry to the manufactures of other countries, we give away the case for free entry of food and raw materials. The inadequacy of this argument appears the moment we notice our own classification of manufactures, as " manufactured and partly manufactured." Suppose that we could put the " manufactured " into a category of their own called Consumption Goods, meaning by that, goods ready for being consumed in the support of human life and not requiring any further pro- cess of labour, the difficulty would at least remain as regards all the others. For all " partly manu- factured " goods are simply the substance and I base — the " material " — of further home industries. ■ To tax them, as I say, has exactly the same effect as to tax raw materials. But, again, among " manufactures " — one would say, among " finished manufactures " — appear tools of all descriptions. But tools surely stand on the same line as raw materials ; they also are necessaries and foundations of all in- IX. TAXING MANUFACTURES 8; dustry. To agricultural countries, the taxing of agricultural implements is a recognised and serious evil. To judge of its effect, one has only to take a walk anywhere in rural France, and witness the peasant working with ploughs only fit for a museum — such ploughs as might be seen on a Roman frieze, but never in English fields. So it comes that, if a country adopt this pro- tection against manufactures, it is driven to make such a complex and detailed tariff, that it is very expensive, very difficult to work, very vexatious, and, at the same time, very open to evasion of all kinds. The contents of any shop window, with its huge variety of articles which must be called " manufactures," show how impossible it is to group them into intelligible classes. And thusj one finds in tariffs such absurdities as that o certain house furnishings being taxed, not a single goods, but as complexes of wood, steel, copper, brass, etc., on each item of which is levied a different duty. It reminds one of the old rail- way casuistry whereby a bicycle was charged for under the classification of " a perambulator with two wheels." ^ From all these considerations, one begins to see ^ Cf. a recent decision affecting an American fruit dealer who imported from Italy, along with a shipment of lemons, a bushel of snails intended for his own table. The authorities decided that a duty on the snails was necessar}', but were for a long time at a loss under what category to place them. Finally, they paid duty as " wild animals " ! 88 TAXING EVERYTHING CH. ix. why it is that, when a government once adopts the protectionist faith, it is driven by force of circum- stances, not to select and categorise, but to tax everything ; and when it tries to let in some things free, or at a reduced rate, is met with a storm of opposition from hundreds of vested interests.^ ^ The kind of problems presented may be illustrated by the treat- ment of colza oil in France. It is manvifactured from the seeds of a kind of turnip, which is also a valuable feeding stuff. To protect the growers, in 1890-2 the Commission of Customs proposed that colza should be protected by a 6 per cent. duty. But the oil is burned in lamps, and the consumers rebelled. To protect their interests, it was proposed that other illuminating oils should be admitted free. Again, colza is largely used in the making of cer- tain soaps, and these soap makers rose in arms. To propitiate them, it was proposed that oleaginous substitutes used in the making of other soaps should also be taxed, and all soap makers put on an equal footing of disadvantage. Thus, to favour the farmer, colza was taxed and lamp oil made dear ; oleaginous sub- stitutes were taxed and all soap made dear. The later develop- ment, I believe, is that, in 1903, the home colza growers asked for the taxation of all oil-producing grains as well. To propitiate the French Colonies on the West Coast of Africa, it was proposed to admit their colza free. The Colonies refused the offer, knowing that they "would have to pay for it" in other ways! One may judge if Sumner exaggerated when he said: "Tax A to favour B. If A complains, tax C to make it up to A. If C complains, tax B to favour C. If any of them still complain, begin all over again." — Protectionism, p. 78. V- CHAPTER X. CONCLUSIONS AS TO PROTECTION. A protective tariff which does not present all manner of anomalies and inequities is impossible. Protection tends to political and com- mercial immorality. It raises cost and checks exports. From what has been said, four conclusions seem to suggest themselves. I. That it is beyond the wit of man to draw up a tariff which will protect whole ranges of industries without causing all sorts of anomalies and inequities. Under Free Trade, self-interest, urged by com- petition, directs capital into the industries which pay, and buys its material and tools wherever it gets them cheapest and best. But Protection, having for its object the restriction of competi- tion, even where it allows the free entrance of food and raw material, taxes other material and tools differentially, according to the circumstances and needs of particular home trades ; that is, not according to any principle of suiting the needs of those trades which use the material and tools, but according to the circumstances and needs of \y / \ 90 PROTECTION TENDS TO POLITICAL chap. Other home trades. Thus one industry may- get in its material at a low rate because the home producers of that material do not need much protection ; another industry, which com- petes with it, may have to pay a high rate for its materia] because the home producers are at a natural disadvantage. Every industry, again, in this artificial system knows its own weakness or strength against outside competition ; but out- siders do not know, and every man keeps his own trade secrets. Even granted, then, that there are, in each business, experts or men who know just what amount of Protection is needed to " protect," no Legislature has the knowledge or the means of getting at the knowledge. If the Legislature simply asks each industry how much Protection it needs, what kind of answer will it get ? Or suppose a tariff is based on the cost of thoroughly efficient home producers, how will this suit the average, or the inefficient ? Will it not tend to throw industry, as it has done in other countries, into the hands of great combinations, and end in monopoly ? II. That Protection tends to political immor- ality. Under Free Trade, the statesman is the voice of the nation. He is elected, indeed, by a section, and he is bound, to a certain extent, to look after ; the particular interests of that section, but the interests of the wider community are always par- amount. He takes his seat as a member of one political party, but that party has, and tries to X. AND COMMERCIAL IMMORALITY 91 carry out, a national programme. At the very- worst, he stands for no selfish or sordid interest. But what becomes of the purity of political life when every elector looks to his member, not to think of the local and national interests, but to give him a tariff high enough to let him earn a profit ? Nay, what becomes of the party to which he belongs when the whip calls one way and the vested interest another ? How, in these circumstances, can the State remain the " armed conscience of the community " ? ^ III. That Protection tends to commercial im- morality. Law ought not to lead men into tempta- 'tion. And nations should have some regard to the temptation which their laws put in the way of other nations. We are all too apt to think that our obligations to obey stop at the boundaries of our own country and the limits of our own laws. There are very few Englishmen who will not do a little smuggling when they cross the channel — the tariffs of other countries, they argue, are " so irrational." And when it is found, not only that tariffs are irra- tional, but that, on the one hand, the adminis- * Where an industry can be made or unmade by a few lines in a tariff schedule, the interest which people take in politics tends to become absorbing in a wrong direction. Although one does not like to cast reflections on one's neighbours, there is some truth in the statement that Americans regard politics as a "business pro- position," and spend large sums in it and on politicians as a business investment. "The day we adopt Protection," said Sir John Brunner, "we may say goodbye to honesty in the House of Commons." 92 PROTECTION HANDICAPS EXPORTS CH. x. tration of them is modifiable by influence or bribery, while, on the other, custom-house officers are ready to pounce, with fine or confiscation, on the error of a careless invoice-clerk, the temptation to regard the tariff as a fair mark for ingenuity is all but irresistible. But this need not be dwelt on. The annals of Protection are full of tales of evasion, of connivance, of bribery — to say nothing of smuggling. IV. That Protection, as it raises the price of everything imported, and, as consequence, the price of everything raised or made at home, increases cost and handicaps exports to neutral markets. Only great natural resources, great superiority of skill, or production on a very large scale, can outweigh this handicap. Unless, in- deed, recourse is had to the complicated and mischievous machinery of " drawbacks " on export, with the extraordinary corollary that the pro- ducer charges dear for his goods at home and sells them cheap to the foreigner ! CHAPTER XI. PROTECTION AS INDIRECT AND DELEGATED TAXATION. Taxation is a price paid to government for common seivices rendered. In its indirect form, certain goods are charged customs and excise ditties, and the extra ive pay goes first to the government, and then comes back to 7j 544,376,000 1894-5. ]] 657,097,000 I90I-2. 5) 866,993,000 ^ For the course of prices from 1873 till now, see p. 191. ''■Board of Trade Blue Book, p. 226. ^Before 1894-5, incomes over^^iso were taxed. XVIII. COMPARE PRUSSIAN RETURNS 173 It should be noted that the comparison with the decade 1868-76 is a comparison with years of abnormal prosperity. Confirmation of this is given by the well-known calculation of what the Chancellor gets for every penny he puts on the Income Tax.^ In 1872-3, the penny yielded - i^i, 741,088 In 1882-3, „ - 1,962,871 In 1892-3, „ - 2,239,856 In 1902-3, „ - 2,580,000 One must be careful in applying this compari- son to the corresponding returns of other nations. It has been asserted that Income-Tax returns in Germany show even better than ours. But Prussia taxes incomes down to ^45 : thirty per cent, of the population show incomes between £\^ and ;^I50: less than five per cent, come under the assessment over ^^150 — which permits us to guess how many come under the ;^45-"^ But, as we do not impose Income Tax till ^160 of income is reached, and give degressive abatements on in- comes under ;^700, our Income-Tax returns witness to the prosperity of the comfortable and wealthy class only. As regards those whose income is under i^i6o, the evidence of prosperity is got from the rise of wages. Next, as to the Savings of the people. In 1882, Sir Robert Giffen calculated these, as a ^ The later yields per penny would be greater but for additional abatements made to the smaller incomes. 2 It seems to be the case that about two-thirds of the population of Prussia, the richest state of Germany, have wages under ^45. 174 FALLACIES OF COMPARISON chap. whole, at ^200,000,000 per year. In a letter to the Times of 3rd Dec, 1903, he estimated them at ;^264,000,000. The Post Office and Savings Banks deposits have grown as under: In 1871, ;^5 5 millions; in I 88 I, ;^8o millions ; in 1891, ;^ii4 millions; in igoi, £ig2 millions; in 1902, £igy millions. A very improper use of statistics is sometimes made in comparing the amount per head of Savings Bank deposits in protected countries with that in our own. According to this, Denmark appears at the top with ;^i 5 lis. 6hd., and Great Britain at the bottom with £4 2s. 5|d. The fallacy of the comparison may be suspected on noticing that France appears second last on the list, with £4 8s. 8^d. The reason, of course, is that France limits her deposits to £60, and Great Britain hers to ;^200, while, in most other countries, there is no limit. Thus the savings of the comfortable and richer classes are compared with those of the working classes. Such comparisons, too, are of no validity unless account is taken of the other opportunities there are for small investors. In a well-banked country like our own, for instance, it may very well be the case that people, having risen to thrifty habits through the savings banks system, may pass on to invest their money in other things — precisely as, in the life of the individual, the money box is exchanged for the savings bank, the savings bank for the ordinary bank, and the bank deposit for wider investments. Mr. Brabrook, indeed, called savings bank deposits "infantile efforts in thrift." XVIII. BANKING STATISTICS I75 Unfortunately, though there are very many ways of investing small savings in this country, the figures are not easily obtainable, particularly over periods of time. It is well known that great numbers of the working classes own their own houses and house property generally, and hold con- siderable stock in industrial companies.^ Trade Union Funds are all working men's money.^ Two figures, happily, are available. One is the funds invested in Co-operative Societies. Comparing the returns for the United Kingdom for the years ending December, 1891 and 1901, the increase was from £\6^ millions to £^ol millions. The other is the deposits in Friendly Societies. Here the increase is from ;^8 millions in 1871 to i^i4 millions in 1881 ; to £26 millions in 1891 ; to ^43 millions in 1901. Banking statistics offer another test of pros- perity. The deposits of all the Joint-stock Banks publishing accounts show the following advance : in 1883, -^400 millions ; in i 888, ^^470 millions ; in l893,;^633 millions; in 1898,^781 millions; in 1903, ^^834 millions. The Clearing-House returns — that is the value of cheques, bills, etc., passed through the London Clearing House — have increased as follows : ^ The 2000 Building Societies in Great Britain and Ireland have jQdi millions of funds. '^The 600 Trade Unions have more than a million and a half members, and nearly £$ millions of funds. The figures here and above are taken from the Presidential Address to Section F of the British Association in 1903 by Mr. Brabrook, Chief Registrar of Friendly Societies. 176 SHIPPING CHAP. £df\ milliards in 1871 ; £6\ milliards in 1881 ; £,^\ milliards in 1891 ; £(^\ milliards in 1901 ; and ;^io milliards in 1903. Whatever the precise importance attached to this as evidence, it shows one thing at least — the universal use we make of banks. But, for people to make use of banks, at least shows that they have money enough to open a banking account, and the figures are, of course, generally, a witness to the increase of trade and the position of London as the banking centre of the world. The state of Shipping is a test of prosperity peculiarly significant as regards this country. The increase in our net tonnage, from 5,690,798 in 1870, to 7,978,538 in 1890, and to 10,054,770 in 1902, speaks for itself, particularly if it is remembered what the " net tonnage," of a nation, constantly renewing its mercantile fleet, means when translated into " carrying capacity." ^ Another test one might apply. It is notoriously difficult to get any figures of home trade, inas- much as every man keeps his business secrets to himself: and yet such figures would give us, perhaps, the best test of national prosperity. But we can get at something that lies at the foundation of many of our industries — the import ^ Statistical comparisons in regard to Shipping are very compli- cated, and, therefore, very often misleading. See Appendix for a full treatment of the subject. ('Reprinted, by kind permission of the Editor, from an article contributed by me to the Glasgcw Herald of 26th November, 1903.) xvrii. IMPORT OF RAW MATERIALS 177 of raw material. We can do nothing with raw material but make it up into finished goods. If these goods are exported, there is a check on one employment of it. But if they are not exported, it shows that the raw material has been used up by the industries of the country, and remains in the shape of goods for consumption at home. If, then, the quantity of raw materials coming into a country increases, it is as good an indica- tion as may be of progress in a great many directions. The following is the increase in quantities of imports from 1886 to 1901 : India-rubber, in cwts., 194,000 to 466,000 Copper, in tons, 197,000 to 264,000 Timber, in loads, 5,500,000 to 9,200,000 Cotton, in cwts., 15,300,000 to 16,300,000 Leather, in lbs., 77,800,000 to 148,300,000 But, beyond these formal and statistical tests, take some not so easily reducible to figures. Where else are the hours of labour so short ? Where is there a country that has an almost universal half holiday on Saturdays and a universal whole holiday on Sundays ? In what other nation does one find whole populations of cities pouring out for a week or ten days in summer, and spending what must be called lavishly at coast or country? Or take a little thing, and therefore all the more significant. The bicycle is, probably, the most beneficent invention of the last generation as regards the health of the people — men, women, and children, M 178 BY ALL THESE TESTS CH. xviii. One may go for twenty miles in the popu- lous parts of rural France, and never meet a working man riding a cycle. In what part of Great Britain, outside of the mountainous districts, would this be possible ? Such, then, are some of the material evidences of our prosperity at the present time. Let it be granted that they are no evidence of national character, of virtue, even of happiness. At least they are not evidence of want of character, of viciousness, of unhappiness. The moral life may be difficult above a certain income ; below it, it is impossible : considering how far most other countries are below our level of income, there seems no doubt, that we are ahead of almost every nation in the material conditions of the Good Life. CHAPTER XIX. EXPORTS AS A TEST OF PROSPERITY. If a country is progressing, its Trade should increase : not necessarily its foreign trade. Falling exports may indicate fuller employment of home industries -which do not export, and increasing exports may indicate Ti-iist dumping or home depression. Free Trade exports, not being exports of superfluity, are no adequate gauge of overflo'i.ving abundance. Among the ordinary tests applied to measure a nation's prosperity, there is one that has not yet been mentioned, the Exports. Before discussing statistics, it would be well, perhaps, to ask what we should expect, as regards its exports, of a country which was otherwise progressing. There is no question that we should expect such a country's total Trade to increase, for the very obvious reasons that the number of mouths to feed is increasing ; that the working capital — the tools and instruments for creating more wealth — is increasing far more rapidly ; and that the Standard of Life is rising, which itself involves that the wealth we are consuming, and taking out of existence as wealth, is increasing, and demands more labour to reproduce it. And i8o FALLING EXPORTS chap. if our trade were altogether foreign trade, or if our foreign trade were, and must be, a constant pro- portion of our total trade, then, of course, our foreign trade ought to be increasing. But, this is an altogether different thing from saying that a nation's exports, by themselves, are an}^ adequate measure of its prosperity and progress, or that the evidence of exports out- weighs the other evidences. Only a couple of years ago, it was generally accepted that the reason why America was not exporting steel, but, on the contrary, importing it, was the extra- ordinary demand for steel in America : her great prosperity at that time was taking the form of increasing fixed plant, railways, and buildings. The same was said of us in the early nineties. We were then so busy that we had relatively little to send abroad. This was the time when other countries got their chance. We absolutely refused foreign orders, not that we did not wish them, but because we could not execute them. It is a suggestive reminder of what people seem so often to forget — that our capital and labour are limited, and that we cannot possiblj^ continue, at the rate of the world's progress, to be the world's provider. So, when one sees falling exports quoted as a sign of national decay, the first thing to do is to look around us at home. And when we do so, and see the enormous development in the trade called House Building ; when we inquire at the Local Government accounts and find that the Local Debt of England and Wales alone — to say XIX. NO SIGN OF DECAY i8i nothing of Scotland and Ireland — has increased from ;^93,ooo,ooo in 1874-5 to ;^3 16,000,000 in 1 900- 1 ; and that ;^ 145,000,000 of that, or 46 per cent., is entered as Reproductive Debt, this is, capital borrowed for the starting of what are virtually State Industries ; — the question arises if it may not very well be the case that the growing capital and labour of this country are finding fuller employment in occupations that do not export. And one may ask, further, if the vast sums now being sunk in better and more sanitary housing for the working classes, are not perhaps a better investment, as regards the nation, than sending out steel rails to develop other countries, or sinking gold mines in the Transvaal. Suppose the vast bogs of Ireland were found to contain a new fuel, or that new sources of coal, petroleum, and the like were discovered in this country, would not capital be withdrawn alike from exporting and from foreign investments and be employed at home ? ^ ^ So, when Mr. Chamberlain compares the alleged 7^% increase in our exports since 1872 with the 30% increase in our population within the same period, and asks, " Can you go on supporting your population at that rate of increase?" (Glasgow speech, 6th Oct., 1903), the only rejoinder is, "What necessary connection is there between exports and the support of the population?" But even here one may join issue with Mr. Chamberlain. His inference is that, if population has increased while exports have not, there must have been less employment for the people. Sir Robert Giffen, however, reminds us that this is not the case theoretically, and is not the case as a fact. The value of manufactured exports contains two elements, the price of the raw materials and the expenses of manufacture. It is the latter only that indicates and measures the employment of British capital and labour. Even i82 WHAT A FREE TRADE NATION chap. But, if falling exports are not necessarily any sign of national decay, are increasing exports any necessary sign of progress ? Look at other coun- tries. The dumping of iron during the last two years from Germany, it is acknowledged, was the dumping of practically bankrupt stock. Yet, no doubt, it accounted for a considerable increase in her exports. Is the dumping from America a sign of her prosperity ? It is a sign of Trusts, but Trusts and prosperity are not synonymous. We are told continually that it is in times of suppose, then, that our manufactured exports, as expressed in terms of value, have not increased, there has been more employment for labour and capital if the price of the raw material has fallen. Now, in 1877, Sir Robert calculated that "the net produce of British labour and capital exported abroad was ;!f 140,000,000." According to the Board of Trade estimate for 1902, it is no less than ;^224, 000,000, the difi'erence being ;^84,ooo,ooo, or 70% of an advance over 1877, in the part of the exports which concerns us. This is confirmed by the calculations of Mr. Bowley. He takes the year 1881 as starting point, "partly for convenience, partly because by that date foreign trade had begun to recover from the sustained depression of 1879." Between 1881 and 1902, the fall in price of the imported raw materials of our textiles was from a level of 100 to a level of 75, or 25%, while the fall in the price of exported textile manufactures was from 100 to 84 only, or 16%. In the same years, the fall in price of imported unmanufactured metals was from 100 to 96, or 4%, while the exports of metal products actually rose from 100 to 112. The conclusion seems inevitable that, even if the values of our exports had remained constant within these years, the amount of labour and capital employed by them had greatly increased. — Economic Journal, Sept. and Dec, 1903, and National Progress in Wealth and Trade. Mr. Bowley's calcula- tion of and deductions from the changes in price of imports and exports, and his comparison with the relative figures for Germany, are among the most valuable contributions which the present controversy has called out. V XIX. EXPORTS IS NOT ITS SURPLUS 183 depression abroad that we may expect dumping, and that, in particular, the dumping we have most occasion to fear is that of the United States Steel Corporation, which is just now pay- ing off its operatives by tens of thousands. But this dumping will no doubt increase her exports. To say that a country is going to the dogs because her exports do not increase, seems to me about as reasonable as saying that, if a man does not go to the Riviera in spring but stays at home, it is because he cannot afford it ! It is always interesting, and sometimes profit- able, to ask the hidden reason of some wide- spread belief Why should exports be counted the gauge and measure of national progress ? It seems to be the assumption that what a nation exports is its Surplus. In Professor Gide's Principles of Political Economy occur these words : " It is certain that for Tyre and Carthage in the old world, and for Venice or the Hanse Towns in the middle ages, trade was everything, and even to-day it holds a very large place in the national life of England. All the same, in great countries at the present time, trade with other nations plays only a moderate part in the general movement of their trade. In this respect, the position of a country differs from that of individuals : in our modern communities, the division of occupation has been pushed to its utmost limits ; no one of us produces almost anything except on behalf of his neighbours, or consumes anything but what has been 1 84 WHAT A FREE TRADE NATION chap. produced by his neighbours. Thus everything we produce and everything we consume must pass by way of trade. It is not so in the case of a country, and particularly of a great country. If we wish to compare such a country with an individual, we should compare it with a landed proprietor living on his estate, who, himself pro- ducing the greater part of what he consumes, has no need of buying outside anything but what he does not himself produce, and, consuming too the greater part of what he produces, has no need of selling outside anything beyond the surplus of his crops." ^ All this is quite true from the standpoint and ideal of a protected country. Since the days of Colbert, France has set before herself the object of being self-sufficient as regards agriculture and manufacture. It is the Nemesis of Protection that her very prosperity makes the realisation of this ideal impossible ; she has a surplus and exports it ; and, in spite of all her planning, the imports which pay for these exports compete with her home producers and prevent the self- sufficiency. But it is equally the aim of a Free-Trade country to break down these national barriers, and send its goods for sale anywhere in the world that it can get a better price than, or even as good a price as, at home. If, then, we think of our exports as the sale of a surplus which we cannot * Third edition, p. 257 ; English translation, p. 237. It is characteristic of the author's anxious and laborious revision that the words do not appear in the last (8th) edition. XIX. EXPORTS IS NOT ITS SURPLUS 185 consume or do not want at home, we shall, of course, regret to see our exports going down ; for the exports, in this case, are thought of as the superfluity of our wealth — the part we can spare and send away in order to buy other things. But when it is realised that foreign countries are not the " dumping ground for surplus," but part of the one common market of a free-trade country, all that a diminution of exports tells us is, that we are not doing so much trade abroad as we did — which may be a good thing or may be a bad thing. The point is that a country may gradually find it more profitable to invest its capital at home, and that the growing wealth may find full employment in industries which do not export. If one con- siders how much of the trained intellect of this country is finding its way into personal services — professional, journalistic, artistic, to say nothing of domestic service — this should be clear enough. CHAPTER XX. THE STAGNATION OF EXPORTS. The statistical stagnation proved by 7'eferefice to 1872 is quite fallacious ; scarcely less so the comparisoti with the period 187 1-5. For t/iese were years (1)0/ abnormal expansion and activity, due, among other things, to the tvar ; {2) of the highest prices, just before the great readjustment of the price level. True, other nations show a greater percentage of total increase in statistical exports. But the only real criterion is exports per head, 7iot per nation ; and here we have a long lead and are increasing it. Although we may freely admit that Exports are not by themselves an adequate gauge and measure of prosperity and progress, there is a good deal to cause us uneasiness if our exports fall off. At least the matter calls for investiga- tion ; and one might have expected the appoint- ment of a Royal Commission long before this to examine and report on it. In 1882, our exports were ^^14,000,000 under those of 1872. In 1885 and in 1886, they were ;^43,ooo,ooo under, and we did not take fright. There was the further excuse for alarm that these were years of great depression. But it was recognised then that times of great prosperity were always CH. XX. RECURRING DEPRESSIONS 187 succeeded by periods of dull trade. Depressions were so regular that some people began to connect them with the appearance of spots on the sun.^ We expected them, and some who were prudent prepared for them. But when things were very bright, producers generally went ahead rushing up mills and increasing output as if the sun would always shine. Then some trade found that it had gone, for the moment, beyond the limits of consumption at paying prices. This trade had to call a halt, and went on short time ; wages and profits were reduced ; purchasing power was thus restricted ; the shops felt it, and curtailed their buying from the manufacturers ; the manufacturers, in turn, limited their demand for raw material and stores ; and, in a short time — no one knew how — trade was found to be " depressed." Then, when we had just realised that the outlook was looking very black, it was suspected that things had taken a turn. Perhaps relief works were started for the unemployed, only to find that the unemployed were finding work in their usual occupations. And, before we well knew what was happening, we were going uphill again, and we heard no more of the depression. These ups and downs of trade were so common that .sensible people accepted them as all in the day's work, and no one thought of blaming Free Trade for them — indeed, we were all ready enough to point out how much worse things were in protected countries. But it seems to ^ Jevons' explanation of the coincidence of the sun spots with bad harvests is well known. 1 88 STAGNATION OF EXPORTS chap. be the case that the past wave of prosperity lasted so long before it broke, and carried us so far, that we think there is something mightily far wrong when there begin to emerge even signs of depression, and we never think of grinning and bearing it, but call lustily for government to " do something." Where, then, is this terrible handwriting on the wall that tells of coming decay, and " descent to the rank of a fifth-rate power ? " The answer given is that, although, by all other tests, the country is prosperous as it never was before,^ the Exports are stagnant. The first thing to do is to look into the facts. If we go back ten years, our exports seem to present a fairly continuous growth, from ^^2 1 6,000,000 in 1894 to ;^2 87,000,000 in 1903. But when the protagonist of the new move- ment opened his campaign in Glasgow on 6th October, 1903, he looked back thirty years, and saw that the increase in exports over 1872 was the very moderate one of i^2 2,000,000. ^"Judged by all available tests, both the total wealth and the diffused well-being of the country are greater than they have ever been. We are not only rich and prosperous in appearance, but also, I believe, in reality." — A. J. Balfour, Economic Notes on Insula}- Free Trade, p. 28. Compare Mr. Chamberlain's words in the beginning of 1902 : " I see no imminent and present danger to the prosperity of this country. During the last five years we have enjoyed an absolutely unparalleled condition of trade, and, although we cannot expect that to last for ever ... to my mind the prospects are extremely good. " XX. SINCE 1872 .89 There is great virtue in round numbers. " Thirty- years ago " looks so much better in a speech than thirty-two or thirty-three or thirty-four. But if he had taken thirty-two years, the increase would have been, not iJ^ 2 2,000,000, but ;^7 8,000,000. If he had taken thirty-three years, it would have been ;^8 8,000,000. If he had taken thirty-four years, it would have been ^^^99,000,000. But no statistician would ever take a single year as his starting point, or compare one single year with another. To eliminate special causes, an average of years must be taken. Let us, then, take quinquennial periods since 1856 — figures before 1854 not being comparable. This comes out as follows : 1856-60, 1861-65, 1866-70, 1871-75, 1876-80, 1881-85, 1886-90, 1891-95, 1896-1900, 1901, - 1902, - 1903, - £124^.2 millions. 144.4 187.8 239-5 201.4 232.3 236.3 227.0 249.1 270.8 277.6 287.0 Here we have a very different story. The average exports of the last three years are nearly ;^4O,O0O,ooo above the average of the " boom years" of 187 1-5. For these were "boom years " in two distinct senses : they were years igo iSji—iSj^ CHAP. of abnormal activity, and they were years of the very highest prices, I. They were years of rapid expansion, of immense railway development, of great activity in the coal and iron trades. But consider, besides, what was happening in Europe, The proudest military monarchy in the world had just collapsed. The Franco-German war began in 1870. Napoleon surrendered at Sedan within the year. Then came the long agony of the beloved city, wrecked inside by its own citizens, and ringed outside with fire ; and the Third Republic was established in 1871, The indemnity was ;^200,ooo,ooo, ^40,000,000, payable the first year, and the remaining «^ 1 60,000,000 in three years thereafter. In direct cost, it was a cheap war, says Giffen, although two great nations carried on unremitting hostilities against each other for nearly eight months, em- ploying altogether some 2| millions of men. But it cost France, he calculates, ;^6oo,ooo,ooo in permanent capital.^ One can understand that here was an immense hole left in the middle of Europe which all nations set themselves to fill up by the pro- ducts of their industry. In particular, France set our factories to work, buying our products to pay Germany. No wonder our exports, which had risen previously by five to ten millions a year, rose with a bound from ^200,000,000 in 1870 to ;^2 5 6,000,000 in 1872. Nor was this all ; while the two nations were at deadly grips with one another, we slipped in, and ^ Essays in Finance : First Series, I. XX. SAUERBECK'S INDEX NUMBER 191 took the increase of trade they naturally would have had. II. The figures given by the statistics of export are, of course, Values, and values depend not only on quantities, but on prices of these quantities. Let us take, then, the movement of prices during these years, using Sauerbeck's Index Number.^ In 1 87 1, the price level was 100. In 1872, it rose to 109. In 1873, it touched 1 1 1, the highest point reached since modern prices were established by the gold discoveries in the middle of the cen- tury. In 1874, it fell to 102; in 1875, to 96; ^ It may be as well to explain the method of Index Numbers. Sauerbeck selected 45 leading and distinct classes of commodities, thus covering fairly the field of human consumption. He collected the wholesale price of these in England between the years 1867 and 1877, so as to eliminate both the years before 1872 and the " boom years" of 1872 and 1873. Taking the average price of each article during these eleven years, he represented it by the figure 100, and thereafter any rise or fall in its price appears as a percentage figure. If wheat, e.g., rose from 25s. to 26s., the figure for wheat would rise from 100 to 104. Thus are conveniently registered changes in the Price Level. Objection may be taken on the ground that each commodity of the 45 has as much importance attached to it as any other ; a rise in pepper affects the price level as much as a rise in wheat. To meet this, other Index Numbers, such as those of Palgrave, have been "weighted"; that is, each article has been given an importance relative to its consumption. Practically, how- ever, it is found that all Index Numbers differ very little in results, and Sauerbeck's, which appears each month in the columns of the Statist, is generally taken as trustworthy. The Index Number begun by Newmarch is still continued in the columns of the Econo- mist. For full discussion of Index Numbers see C. M. Walsh, The Mcasuremait of General Exchange Value, and Professor Edgeworth's Memoranda in the Reports of the British Association for 1887, 1888, and 1889. 192 THE GREAT FALL chap. and from that year it fell fast and heavily till, in 1886, it was 69. But this was not the bottom. The lowest year was 1896, when it touched 61. For the ten years, 1888- 1897, it averaged 6'], and for the ten years 1893- 1902, it averaged 66. This was a stupendous fall of prices. It meant that, as a whole, every article which sold for 100 shillings, or pence, or pounds in 1871, was selling in 1896 for 61 shillings, or pence, or pounds. The fall was due to the inter- action of two causes. One was the immense cheapening of costs, by the inventions which increased the speed and carrying power of ships, and by the opening of the Suez Canal, which saved a journey from Western Europe to India of 3750 miles, and brought goods direct into the heart of the Continent. This stimulus to pro- duction and increase of trade gave money more work to do — just as an increase of traffic would make a greater demand on railway trucks. The other cause was that, just at the same time, there was a great falling off in the money supply available. Up till 1873, silver was a full-valued money, used as legal tender by France, Germany, Italy, Belgium, Holland, and the United States. It was linked with gold by the bimetallic system, formally established at the beginning of the last century, whereby 15^ oz. of silver were accepted as equal in value to one oz. of gold practically all over the world. That system collapsed in 1873, and silver became no longer the money of XX. IN PRICES 193 Europe. The whole of the money work had to be done by gold, plus the credit instruments superimposed. Unfortunately, the production of gold did not respond to the call upon it. Its output, after rushing up to a certain point, rather fell off. It was not till near the end of the century that the discoveries in the Transvaal and Australia began steadily and greatly to increase the output, and even this was checked by the Boer War. The result was that the exchange value of every commodity had to be named in a smaller number of coins, at the same time that the number of commodities which had to be named had enormously increased. We are still under the influence of that re- adjustment. Prices went up from 1896 to 1900, when they reached 75. Then they fell again. Now they are at 69. That is, the prices of to-day are practically the same as the prices of 1886. The impropriety, then, of comparing the values of exports in 1872 with the values of exports in 1902, needs no further proof. It is com- paring a time when prices were at a level of 9s. id. with a time when they were at a level of 5s. 9d. Thus "stagnation in exports," between 1872 and now, means that we are sending immensely more goods than we were, and probably em- ploying more labour and more machinery to produce them, while the fall in prices alone makes this appear as if the increase were trifling. It is not stagnation ; it is change of price. N 194 FALLACY OF PERCENTAGES chap. This is confirmed by the following cal- culation. If the prices of 1873 had been maintained till now, our exports would have been as under : 1873, ;^2 5 5 millions. 1883, 295 millions, instead of ^240 millions. 1893. 329 » » 218 1902, 418 „ „ 278 „ On these grounds, it must be said that, to take the year 1872 as the basis of a com- parison, is utterly unpardonable ; at least, it would be unpardonable in a statistician or an economist. Indeed, one may go further, and say that, to take even the quinquennial period embracing the years 187 1-5, as a basis for com- parison with any other quinquennial period, is quite inadmissible. But, it may be said, granted that our ex- ports, by comparison with previous years, are not stagnant, is it not the case that the exports of other countries have increased faster than ours? This is quite true. It is the case that, between the years 1891 and 1901, Norway has increased her exports by 24.7 per cent. ; Portugal, by 31.3 per cent. ; Denmark, by 40.9 per cent. ; Italy, by 57.1 per cent; Japan, by 107.1 percent. Eng- land, on the other hand, has increased hers only by 13.3 per cent. All the same, this is a good instance of what is called the Fallacy of Percentages, now so XX. FALLACY OF PERCENTAGES 195 common among careless or dishonest contro- versialists. It was delightfully illustrated by Mr. Asquith in a recent speech. During one of our wars, he said, the temperance people in this country set on foot an inquiry as to the relative healthiness and powers of endurance of the total abstainers in the army as compared with the free drinkers, one regiment being taken as sample. The return made was that, of the total abstainers in this regiment, 50 per cent, had died and the other 50 per cent, had been invalided home, and this was very terrible and dishearten- ing to the temperance people. But a different aspect was put on the matter when it turned out that, of the total abstainers in the regiment in question, one was killed in action and the other had had a sunstroke ! The truth or falsity of such comparisons altogether depends on the quantum with which they start. Thus, when we notice that Japan, in 1891, showed ;^ 1 2,664,000 of exports, while Great Britain showed ^247,235,000, the reason of the dis- parity in percentages stands revealed. A girl of twenty-five will double her age in twenty-five years ; a man of fifty never will. But there is no such fallacy in comparing, with our own, countries like Germany and the United States, whose exports are very much on the same scale as ours. Taking 1872 as the year of comparison, Mr. Chamberlain pointed out that, while our increase, under Free Trade, was only ;^2 2,000,000, the increase of Ger- many in the same time, under Protection, was 196 THE TRUE TEST IS chap. ;^5 6,000,000, and the increase of the United States ;^ 1 10,000,000.^ Assuming the accuracy of these figures, and the propriety of taking 1872 as start, the ques- tion immediately emerges whether this is a legitimate comparison, and the answer is that it is not. It is comparing nation with nation, instead of the individuals of one nation with the individuals of another. It is no better than comparing the wealth of two households, with- out asking whether the two households contain the same number of persons. This is a grave matter, and it cannot be put too plainly. What does material progress mean to us ? One may take it to mean that we, as indi- viduals, are " making more money " as we say, and the ordinary way of making more money is by ^ It is not necessary to say any more as to the alleged ;^22, 000,000, or 7^ per cent., of British increase since 1872. As for the German increase of /56,ooo,ooo, it is impossible to say much, for a different reason— that I do not know where Mr. Chamberlain got the figure. The German Empire came into being only in 1872. Bremen and the greater part of the State of Hamburg did not come into the ZoUverein till 1888 and 1889 respectively. The Board of Trade Blue Book, in its table of exports from Germany, leaves a blank before 1880, with the words " information not available." And again, in 1897, there was a complete break in continuity; a large proportion of the " improvement" traffic was added to the special exports, "so that for any years before and after that date," says a Foreign Office Report, No. 490, "no correct comparisons can be made." As regards the American increase of £1 10,000,000, it should be noted, in addition to the other considerations mentioned, that America has meantime given up competing for the oversea traffic, and that, if she increases her foreign trade, either of importing or exporting, her visible exports must increase from the mere necessity of paying for our invisible exports. XX. EXPORTS PER HEAD 197 doing more trade. If then, we, individually, find that we are doing more trade this year than we did last, we are satisfied. If, again, we look across to France, and find that their individuals are pro- gressing in the same proportion, we may conclude that both " nations " are doing equally well. In short, it is the prosperity and progress of the individual that concerns us. We should never think of judging the " Standard of Life " of a people by anything else than their consump- tion per head. Neither should we count that a firm of two partners was worse off than a firm of four, if the latter firm was making ;!^2000 a year and the former iJ"iooo. If this is true of income and of trade generally, it is no less true of that department of trade which exports. It is the exports per head that concern us. This calculation was made in 1899 by Sir Alfred E. Bateman, then Comptroller General at the Board of Trade. The figures were as follows : Since 1875, the exports per head of the four great countries remained nearly stationary, and stood in the following rank : Great Britain, £6 ; France, £1 15s.; Germany, ^3 7s.; America, £2 I 8s. Is it a deplorable thing that, head for head, we should not have gone in front of our rivals ? What better could we expect than to keep our long lead ? Trade is done by individuals for individuals. As individuals increase in numbers it should be expected that they will col- lectively do more trade, just because there are more of them. If, to take an extreme example 198 EXPORTS PER HEAD chap. all trade were foreign trade ; if all these millions in the various countries were engaged in ex- porting ; and if each was making just a living wage by it : then, if the increasing numbers of one generation were to remain in life, they would each require to be exporting just as much per head as the smaller numbers of the previous generation were exporting ; in this case, it would be seen that the absolute increase in ex- ports of one nation over another is a natural phenomenon of growing population, and not in the least a sign of aggressive trade policy. Con- sidering that Germany has a population of some 56,000,000, and America a population of nearly 80,000,000 ; considering also that our population increases about i per cent, per year against Germany's \\ per cent., and America's 3^ per cent. ; it follows that, if German and American exports did not increase absolutely, it would be a sign that Germany and America were falling back — assuming, of course, that exports are a fair indication of progress. In light of these figures, the idea that we are losing ground because America makes up on us, or passes us, in total value of exports, or that France is losing ground because her total exports do not increase, dis- appears. There seems to be an idea abroad that we should not only be ahead of the world in foreign trade, and keeping our lead, but should be in- creasing it. How, in reason, can we expect this ? Even if the populations of the various countries were the same, how could we expect it ? Is it XX. OUR LONG AND INCREASING LEAD 199 true that we are the most enterprising, or best educated, or most inventive ? But as neither populations nor rates of increase are the same, Germany and America may well be expected to forge slowly ahead, because, in these countries, there is a cumulative increase of producing units. And this is not an increase of ill-fed, ill-educated, lethargic black or yellow races, but an increase of people as good as ourselves, and, in the case of America at least, of people who have some busi- ness qualities which are not so prominent in the mother race. I submit that, unless we are to take the absurd view that we should increase our foreign trade as we increase our fleet — that is, on the principle of being always equal to the two greatest nations — we may rest pretty well content with the fact that, in spite of our slowly increasing popu- lation, we have such a long lead of other nations, and keep neck for neck with them in increase. But, as it happens, the latest figures show that we are actually increasing our lead. Since the above calculation was made, three years have passed. Taking the triennial period 1900-2, we find that Great Britain heads the list by no less than £6 17s. 2d., while Germany shows £\ is. I id., and the United States ;^3 i6s. 6d. That is to say, Great Britain and the United States have both added about i8s. per head, while Germany has added only 14s. pd. CHAPTER XXL EMPLOYMENT AS AFFECTED BY EXPORTS AND IMPORTS. It is said that we are exporting raw tnaterials which employ little labour, and importing manufactures which, made at home, might employ much. Btit Coal employs t/ioj-e labour for its value than j)iost marmfactures. Most of the manufactured imports, again, are materials of our industries. Of the remainder, there are so??ie our conszmters will have ; some, foreigners can 7>iake better ; some 'would require skilled labour, which, probably, is already profitably employed in other ways. But are we not forgetting that all these imports must be paid for, and that, to take over the making of them ourselves, is to displace those who now are making for export 1 Neither Free Trade nor Protection, in themselves, can secure employment for a nation. If it is proved that there is no stagnation of exports ; that the total exports are increasing satisfactorily, and the exports per head even more satisfactorily ; one would think that there is no reason for alarm, or for any attempt to regulate either demand or supply. The imports from abroad are being paid for in goods produced at home ; as the former increase, so do the latter. But here we encounter an objection which seems to strike many as plausible ; — that the things we CH. XXI. DIMINUTION OF EMPLOYMENT 201 are exporting are not the right things, and that the things we are importing are the wrong things. England, it is said, has long been the workshop of the world and should remain so ; to secure this, we ought to be importing raw materials and sending them out as manufactures, whereas, as a fact, we are exporting more and more raw material, and importing more and more manufactures. The preliminary question, of course, is whether this statement would be accepted if it were found that the export of raw materials is relatively more profitable than the export of manufactures.^ But we may pass this by, and concentrate our attention on the suggestion which has caught hold on the public during the present controversy, that raw materials employ little labour and manufactures employ much ; and that, in these two ways, the character of our foreign trade is diminishing the Employment of the nation. If one were content with a cheap victory, it might be asked. Is it employment we want ? Have we not, up till now, been rejoicing that we are in such comfortable circumstances that we could reduce the working day to nine hours ? Have not many good people been saying that the ^ Mr. Bowley has done good service in raising this point. He shows that, between 1S81 and 1902, while our exports of manufac- tured textiles have fallen from a price level of 100 to a level of 84, exported raw materials show a rise in price from 100 to 1 14, and he adds that " the price of coal does not account to any great extent for the phenomenon except in 1900 and 1901." This, of course, in itself does not prove relative profitableness, but it suggests questions. Compare footnote, p. 203. G 202 DIMINUTION OF EMPLOYMENT chap. time had come for the golden age : " eight hours for sleep, eight hours for play, eight hours for work, and eight shillings a day"? If, by all the ordinary tests, our people are getting wealthy hand over hand, may we not rest easy in our minds about not having enough work to do ? But the retort would be a little cheap, and is, besides, not quite straightforward. That we have been able to reduce the statutory hours of labour in this country, is certainly not due to any cur- tailment in our demand for goods, or to any con- tentment with the amount of wealth we already have. If, indeed, we were satisfied to live as our ancestors did, a very few hours of labour would produce over-supply. But as wealth increases and the standard of living rises, wants increase, and the new wants of a progressive people make more demands on industry than the simpler ones did. There is not less product from the working world, but infinitely more, the explanation being that we have been, in many directions, economising human wear and tear by transferring the heavy work to machinery, and, moreover, sending larger amounts of the growing labour into occupations which know no limit of factory acts and hours. In the abstract, then, there is not the slightest fear of labour, as a whole, having too little to do. But it may be quite honestly argued that the foreigner is taking some of our employment from us. I. Let us ask, then, what raw material it is, the export of which should give us anxiety. The answer, of course, is Coal. In 1897 and XXI. COAL AN IRREPLACEABLE CAPITAL 203 1898, we exported 35 million tons; in 1899, 41 millions; in 1900, 44 millions; in 1901, 41 millions; in 1902, 43 millions — roughly, about a fifth part of our total output. There is an argument often advanced about the export of coal which does deserve serious attention. It is that coal is " natural capital," given us by a beneficent Creator ; that it is the very source of our manufacturing greatness ; that, unlike other forms of capital, it is irreplaceable; and that, accordingly, it is shortsighted to dig it out, as we are doing, and send it away to the foreigner.^ It is very much the argument put forward by the old-fashioned professor against printing lectures he had repeated for many years ; that, if he did, he would have nothing left to say. Considering, however, that we are not merely sending coal but selling it, it seems to me that we are exchanging a very precarious form of wealth for other forms which are, probably, less ^ It should be noted that a large proportion — probably as much as one-half — of the coal which appears as exported is really for navigation purposes. Very little is sent abroad for manufacturing. It has been pointed out by Mr. D. A. Thomas that " coal enters into the production of every manufactured article, and therefore the export of such commodities indirectly involves the export of coal. For instance, every ton of pig iron requires the consumption of something like two tons in its production, and its shipment abroad virtually means, therefore, the export of two tons of coal, while the export of a ton of wrought iron or steel means considerably more. Consequently if any restriction is placed on the export of coal on tl\e ground that we are shipping abroad capital that cannot be replaced, logically we must place a corresponding restriction on the export of every manufactured article into the production of which coal enters." — British Industries under Free Trade, p. 367. 204 LABOUR COST OF COAL CHAP. precarious. Our coal will last, according to a moderate estimate, for another hundred years without the cost of raising it being increased. At present it realises a comparatively high price. But what will become of that high price if a new fuel is found, as it probably will be long before the century is out ; or if the long-sought- for economy is discovered which will save the 90 per cent, energy that now goes out of the chimney ; or if the opening up of coal deposits nearer our foreign markets diverts the supply from us ? But when the export of Coal is objected to on the entirely different ground that it is a product which employs little labour in the getting, there is no hesitation about the answer. It is that the price of our ordinary coal is made up of 60 per cent, of pure wages, while the price of Welsh coal is made up of 80 per cent, of wages. That is to say, coal, value for value, employs far more labour than manufactures generally, the wages element in our cotton manufactures, for instance, being estimated at about 50 per cent, of the total value, less that of the raw material.^ Is it possible that those who make assertions in this irrespon- sible way were comparing bulks and not values, and thus came to the conclusion that, as compared with a small parcel of jewellery, a cwt. of coals must contain little labour, because it takes a cart to hold a few shillings worth ? II. What has just been said disposes of the suggestion that, in importing manufactures, we ^ Board of Trade Blue Book, p. 360. XXI. IMPORT OF MANUFACTURES 205 are curtailing the employment of our own people, in so far as we are depriving ourselves of the chance of making such manufactures for export. If we export coal in payment of imports, we are employing more labour than we should by ex- porting manufactures. But it does not dispose of the objection that we have been, and should remain, the workshop of the world, and that there is something wrong if we are importing more and more manufactured goods that compete with ourselves. Let us, then, look at the imports complained of According to the Board of Trade Blue Book, p. 73, our imports of manufactured or partly manufactured articles from the seven great nations, in 1902, were as follows: Italy, £2 millions; Russia, £2, millions; Germany, i^ 16 millions; Bel- gium, i^20 millions ; Holland, i^20 millions ; United States, ;^20 millions; France, ;^3 i millions. In all, £\ 12,000,000. Take, first, the partly manufactured articles, and analyse the lists. A mere glance at the ;^20 millions from the United States shows that, of this, £\oh millions are what certainly would be called " raw materials " by an ordinary un- instructed man. There are £2\ millions of unwrought and partly wrought Copper, £2,^ millions of Leather, £i\ millions of various kinds of Oil, £h million of pig and sheet Lead, ;i^900,ooo of Paraffin and paraffin wax, i^i 36,000 of crude Zinc, i^i 28,000 of Slates, ;^i 2,000 of Stones, etc.^ ^ ' ' These are not the sort of things which we speak of as manufactures' when our own export trade is concerned. It is 2o6 SUPPOSE WE COULD MAKE ALL chap. There is nothing quite so obvious in the imports from the other countries ; but a care- ful examination would show that there are comparatively few things in the i^i 12,000,000 which do not form the basal or auxiliary materials of many of our industries. Take, second, the wholly manufactured articles. Among the larger categories, from Germany come Works of Art, Bronzes, China, Machinery, Musical Instruments, Toys : from Belgium, Clocks, Em- broidery and Needlework, Hats and Bonnets, Laces, Pictures, Silk Stuffs : from Holland, Buttons and Studs, Leather goods. Silks, Pictures : from France, Embroidery, Artificial Flowers, Hats and Bonnets, Laces, Musical Instruments, £^ millions of Silk manufactures, and over £^ millions of Woollen manufactures : from Italy, Works of Art, Stones. The list is a long one, and contains a great number of small imports. There is no doubt that we could make all these things. But we forget three things. The first is that we are not only the "workshop of the world," but the wealthiest consuming nation of the world. We demand whatever takes our fancy, and we should not be in the least willing to limit our consumption to the peculiar products of Great Britain. We do not take the word of our milliners and dress- makers that English goods are every bit as good as French ; our womenkind send to Paris for hats an obvious reflection that, if slates, stones, crude zinc, and copper are to be spoken of as ' manufactures,' we might as well include coal in the same category." — Sir Robert Giffen, in a letter to the Times. XXI. THE MANUFACTURES WE IMPORT 207 and dresses, and make special trips to the Bon Marche for frills and furbelows. We should never think of shutting out works of art from Italy because there are artists in England, or pianos from Germany in order to force our musicians to play on English ones. We should regard any such proposals as nothing better than the old attempt to put back the clock of civilisation and enact sumptuary laws to our own hurt. The second is that, as regards many of these manufactures, there is a very good reason why we do not prefer British made goods. We import, for instance, £\\ millions of ladies' woollen dress fabrics, mostly from Roubaix, because, rightly or wrongly, we consider French colour-dyeing superior to Bradford dyeing. The third is that, even where we could make things as beautiful, and as cheap, and as good as the foreigner, we have not an unlimited amount of capital, and the capital we have may be fully and more profitably employed in making other things. And we have very far from an unlimited amount of skilled labour. True, in bad times we have a good many unemployed, and, at all times, we have several millions of wage earners below the efficiency standard. But do these millions consist of watch makers, musical instrument makers, artists, and the like ? Or are they people who could not be set to such skilled work, whatever wages were offered them ? Are the " unemployables " not vastly more than the " unemployed " ? Is our employment really 2o8 IMPORTED COMMODITIES chap. curtailed because we do not import things which we might make ? ^ Yet this is persistently represented as " loss " — as if one could lose what one never had ! " In thirty years the total imports of manufactures which could just as well be made in this country have increased ;!^8 6,000,000, and the total ex- ports have decreased i^6,ooo,ooo. We have lost ^92,000,000. ^^92,000,000 of trade that we might have done here has gone to the foreigner, and what has been the result for our own people ? The Board of Trade tells you, you may take one- 1 If all the labour that is employable were employed, there would, of course, be no question about the advantage of such imports. But the unemployed are always with us. It is a little startling to find that, in the best times, there are always some 2 per cent, of workers, in the organised trades, who do not find work. To whatever cause this may be ascribed, it certainly cannot be laid at the door of Free Trade. But, as regards the present question, what would require to be proved is that the amount of unemployment in protected countries is less than in our own, and this would be difiicult to do. There are no adequate and strictly comparable international statistics as to skilled and unskilled labour— remembering that such statistics, to be of any value, must extend over a period long enough to allow of being put into rates of progress — and none which dis- tinguish what Mr. Booth has called the three phases of irregularity, the short, the seasonal, and the cyclical. In this country we have the returns of unemployed made to the Board of Trade by the principal trade unions, the figures including London dock labourers, iron and steel workers, the building, textile, engineering and other trades. It may be noted that the mean percentage of unemployed during 1903 was 5.1. The average percentage for the ten years 1894-1903 was 4.1. Between 1888 and 1903 the percentage varied from 2.1 to 7.5. "It is quite impossible to study these figures," says Mr. Bowley, "without coming to the conclusion that the years 1890 to 1900, at any rate, were years of exceptionally good employ- ment."— Tiiw^;^, Nov., 1903. XXI. ARE AT LEAST PAID FOR 209 half of the export as representing wages. We therefore have lost ;^46,ooo,ooo a year in wages during the thirty years. That would give em- ployment to nearl}' 600,000 men at 30s. per week of continuous employment. That would give a fair subsistence for these men and their families, amounting to 3,000,000 persons."^ This quota- tion brings us back to first principles. Suppose we did manufacture all these things at home and stopped the imports from the foreigner, would this be pure gain ? Have we forgotten the pro- ducers here who have, all the time, been making the exports that must be sent to pay for these imports, and whose employment would be cur- tailed in the same proportion as the new employ- ment increased ? As Mill put it — and put it so tersely that the completeness of the statement is apt to be overlooked : " The alternative is not between employing our own people and foreigners, but between employing one class and another of our own people. The imported commodity is always paid for, directly or indirectly, with the produce of our own industry ; that industry being, at the same time, rendered more productive, since, with the same labour and outlay, we are enabled to possess ourselves of a greater quantity of the article." ^ ^ Mr. Chamberlain at Newcastle, Oct. 20, 1903. Observe that the ;^6,ooo,ooo we once had is lumped with the ^46,000,000 we never had, and both are called "loss"! Is this any better logic than the schoolboy's "Pins have saved many thousands of lives — by people not swallowing them " ? ^ Principles of Political Economy, v. 10, i. O 2IO IMPORTS AS AN ''ATTACK'' chap. This kind of appeal to popular ignorance is thoroughly bad. It would be just as true, and just as false, if " Englishmen " and " Scotsmen " were substituted respectively for " home pro- ducers " and " foreign producers," and the state- ment were made to London working men that they were losing employment by the goods that Glasgow working men were making for them. What the increase of foreign manufactured im- ports shows is simply the increased division and specialisation of industry — the area of com- petitive service widening beyond the national boundaries, in manufactures as in everything else.^ What very much hides the absurdity from us is the now fashionable way of speaking of foreign competition in terms borrowed from warfare. Im- ports are an " attack " ; when they become numerous, they are a " conspiracy " ; and we are asked if we are going " to take all that lying ^ Perhaps the case may be put shortly thus. Belgium has been employing a capital of ;i^ioo,ooo in making goods for London and Leeds. London and Leeds have each been employing a capital of ;i^50,ooo in making goods for Belgium. The import of Belgian goods is stopped by a prohibitive tariff. By the same act, the export of English goods pro tanto is stopped. The London capital finds a market for its products in Leeds, and the Leeds capital finds a market for its products in London. Only British goods are now found in the two markets. But has this increased employ- ment? Increased employment could only come from London and Leeds putting down new capital, and exchanging their pro- ducts. But then they might just as well sell the goods produced by this new capital to Belgium and import Belgian goods in return. There is no more employment in the one case than in the other. XXI. EMPLOYMENT UNDER PROTECTION 211 down. " ^ Seeing that we have been doing just the same kind of thing to foreign countries for about a century, the question surely is : Are we all, then, engaged in a mortal struggle to destroy one another's industries ? Or are we sending each other cheap goods to sell in one another's markets — extending the area of Competitive Ser- vice beyond our home boundaries ? The subject of Employment as affected by the character of goods imported and exported suggests the wider subject of Employment as affected by a protective system. It is sometimes assumed that Protection secures the employment of the nation better than Free Trade does. There are really two questions here, and the issue is confused unless they are kept distinct. The first is : Does Protection give more employment ? the second : Does it secure more regular employment ? I. The idea that Protection gives more employ- ment seems to argue rather dangerous ignorance of what does employ the nation. Any govern- ment can " make work " for its citizens so long as the pockets of the taxpayers hold out ; but this is ^"Agriculture has been practically destroyed. Sugar has gone. Silk has gone. Wool is threatened. Cotton will go. How long are you going to stand it ? " says a great orator. And his hearers, being Englishmen and born fighters, stand on the seals, and cheer. Sir Edward Grey was not far wrong : "The time is coming when, if an Englishman says that England is prosperous, he will be called a Pro- Boer ; while if anybody writes telling of a trade that is doing badly, he will very likely be called 'one of our leading experts,' and have his letter sent to the Times, with Mr. Chamberlain's imprimatur." 212 EMPLOYMENT UNDER PROTECTION chap. simply diverting the employment of the people from its ordinary channels into the channels on which the government spends. Any war scare, for instance, that sends the Clyde shipyards a few cruisers to build, gives employment to one of the great trades, and secures the activity of the many subsidiary trades dependent on it. But the extra money taken out of the taxpayers' pockets for any such purpose leaves the citizens generally with so much less to spend, and the other parts of the kingdom suffer by Glasgow's gain. The only thing that can increase general employ- ment is the increase of productiveness ; that is to say, in essence, the increase of wealth. The " demand for labour " is not a fund of money in the pockets of employers. If there were no out- side employer, and each gang of workers paid one of their number a wage to organise them, the wages of these workers would depend on the amount they could produce and the prices at which they sold it. It is the whole product of the working world that determines and limits the " demand " for all the factors of production which represent the working world ; the greater that product, the greater the demand for labour among other factors.^ In short, we employ each ^The whole matter is contained in these pregnant words of Marshall: "The net aggregate of all the commodities produced is itself the true source from which flow the demand prices for all these commodities, and therefore for the agents of production used in making them. Or, to put the same thing in another way, this national dividend is at once the aggregate net product of, and the sole source of payment for, all the agents of production within the country ; it is divided up into earnings of labour ; interest of capital ; XXI. REGULARITY OF EMPLOYMENT 213 Other. The more I produce, the more I hold up in my hand as the price of the services which I ask you to render me, and, the more we all pro- duce, the more do we all have to offer. If we call this product the National Income or National Dividend, the question resolves itself into this : whether the National Income is increased by Pro- tection ; whether a government, by taking thought, can secure that its individual producers produce more. It is a pious imagination that a very wise government, by taking over the industries of the nation, might do better than private enterprise and produce a greater net product. But this is not the question ; all we are concerned with is whether a government, by taxing goods from out- side, can give its individual producers greater stimulus and better direction than free competition with other countries can. As a matter of theory, this would be difficult to prove, and experience does not seem to give it any support. II. The idea that Protection ensures greater regularity of employment seems to rest on the belief that, under it, more security is given to capital by the partial monopoly of the home market. This also seems to verge on the dan- gerous doctrine that the giving of employment is the end of the matter: it has a family resemblance to the popular belief that, by reducing the hours of labour, the unemployed will be taken up. The and, lastly, the producer's surplus, or rent, of land and of other differential advantages for production.'"— /'/-/w/>/^^, p. 609. See my Distribution of Income, which is, practically, a working out of this single paragraph. 214 NEITHER SYSTEM CAN SECURE chap. protected industries occupy much the same posi- tion as particular industries favoured by govern- ment orders at the expense of the taxpayers ; regularity of employment is secured at the expense of the quantity produced ; the demand for labour ultimately suffers by the diminution of the national product. Here, again, confirmation by statistics or experience is entirely lacking. That an industry declines and disappears under Free Trade is no proof either that Free Trade has killed it or that Protection would have kept it alive.^ The fact is that neither Protection nor Free Trade will ensure constant equilibrium of demand and 1 "The cotton manufacture is generally regarded as the most stable and thoroughly organised of our great industries, but it appears from the census returns that in the single state of Massachusetts 21 mills, with an aggregate of 154,016 spindles, and i mill with iSo looms, which reported to the census of 1890, were not in existence when the census of 1900 was taken. Seven of these mills with 47,680 spindles were dismantled and their machinery sold ; 13 mills, with 101,156 spindles, stood idle in 1900, or had been turned to other manufacturing purposes. One mill was burnt and not rebuilt ; and one was consolidated with a neighbouring mill under new corporate organisation. In addition to these cotton mills there were 15 mills manufacturing cotton small wares, which went out of existence during the decade. Such a record indicates that unprofit- able operation is constantly in progress side by side with more successful enterprise. In this particular industry, advance in machinery has been so rapid that it is calculated that a cotton mill must practically renew its machinery once every ten years if it would keep its plant in a condition that will permit profitable production, in competition with other establishments manufacturing the same class of goods, with the latest pattern of machinery, and the most labour-saving devices, the most effective methods of management, and facilities for the largest production at the lowest labour cost." — Twelfth Census of the United States, 1900, vol. vii. p. 65. XXI. REGULAR EMPLOYMENT 215 supply, and this is the only way in which steadi- ness of employment might be secured. Protected producers, just like Free Trade producers, put themselves at the mercy of demand ; they make, for the most part, in anticipation of orders, and, often enough, they find that their anticipations were mistaken. All goes well so long as trade is brisk. But when a lull comes, supply cannot easily be slacked off; more is being turned out than is taken off; and depression sets in, spread- ing its contagion through the organised web. All this is obviously independent either of Free Trade or Protection. All one would say is that Pro- tection, as tending to attract capital and labour into artificial channels and oversupply them, rather acts against the mobility which is the best security of regular employment. CHAPTER XXII. PREFERENTIAL TARIFFS. Preference to our Colonies involves ptttting on tariffs against the eutside world. Disguise it as ive may, it is Protection. The proposal of Preference to parts of the British Empire over the outside world is not a new one. It prevailed for two centuries from the passing of the Commonwealth Navigation Act, and was abolished only by the Whig Government which succeeded Peel's, and received his support. But there was this difference at any rate. Nobody thought of calling it Free Trade. It was part of the Protective system under which we lived. Suppose we now resume the discarded prin- ciple of Preferential Tariffs. It is not capable of being carried out unless there is a tariff on which to give a preference — " the penniless traveller sings in the presence of the robber." Thus, as the first step in Preference, we must impose a tariff. In the long contest between the Colonies and ourselves whether they are to adopt Free Trade or we are to resume Protection, the Colonies CH. XXII. RECIPROCirV TREATIES 217 have won. The voices of Canada and Australia have shouted down the old country. We resume Protection then.^ But it is a very peculiar Protection. Germany and America justify their protective system, and escape its worst evils, by the fact that they have Free Trade within their Empires. The United States is by far the largest Free Trade unit in the world — some of her 45 states are larger than the entire German Empire — and it may very reasonably be contended that her prosperity is due, not to Protection, but to this Free Trade. But we are not to have free trade within our Empire. Every constituent member of it is, apparently, to have the liberty of erecting what tariff it likes against other members, so long as its duties are lower to Great Britain and to British possessions than they are to the rest of the world.- It is best described as a British Empire Series of Reciprocity Treaties.^ ' It shows what a hold the word has on the unpleasant memories of the nation, that the name of Protection should be vigorously protested against. Just as Mr. Gladstone thought that he had gained something when he replaced the word Boycott by the word Preferential Dealing, so do many try to insist that Preferential Tarifts are not Protection. We want to admit our kinsmen free to our house ; if we emphasise it by shutting the door in the faces of our friends — well, it is merely a regrettable incident ! ^ Even this is not clear. New Zealand proposes to give a prefer- ence to Great Britain, but she adds that the same preference will be given to any country which gives her equal terms. All the time, so far as one can make out. Great Britain is the only pan of the Empire which is not to have this privilege, but is always to give a preference to the Colonies whatever they do. ^At present the scheme has scarcely advanced beyond the 2i8 PROTECTION FOR THE COLONIES CH. xxii Disguise it as we may, it is preferential treat- ment for themselves against the world outside the Empire, that this small group of self-governing colonies is asking. One might even say that it is Protection for Canada and Australia. We are to impose a tariff against the world, not because we want to shut the world out, but in order that we may take the tariff off the Colonies. Considering that the imports from Canada and Australia into this country amount to £df2\ millions, and that the imports from all the six self-governing colonies put altogether amount to only i^5 9,800,000 ; while the imports from the Free Trade portion of the Empire amount to ;^47, 200,000, and the imports from foreign countries to ^^421 millions, the demand needs looking into.^ enunciation of the principle. What, for instance, is to be the relation of one colony to another, or of the self-governing colonies to the other colonies, or of any colony to a "possession"; whether India and the Crown colonies are to remain free trade or to put on tariffs ; whether the Protectorates, or countries in the anomalous condition of Egypt, are to be included ; whether there is to be preference as regards all the imports taxed ; or even what the posi- tion of revenue taxes is to be : — all these are details waiting the mandate of the country before they are discussed. One might hint that the possibility of such a scheme — to say nothing of its advantage — depends on the working out of the details. ^See Annual Statement of Trade (Cd. 1617), 1903, vol. ii., p. 6, and Board of Trade Blue Book, p. 408. CHAPTER XXIII. THE CANADIAN PREFERENCE. Its results are disappointing. It changed a decline into an in- crease, but the increase is not proportional to that of other countries which have no preference. As differentiated, the tariff still presses most heavily on us, and favours the foreigner. There is at least one part of the scheme to which we are not hkely to object. It was not our wish that the Colonies ever adopted Protec- tion, but, since they have done so, it seems as if the least thing they could do is to give us a Preference. Perhaps, then, we may begin by con- sidering what has been the result of the Canadian Preference. For some years after the Federation of the separate provinces into the Dominion, in 1868, Canada enjo)'ed a comparatively low tariff. In 1874, there was a period of depression, and the Conservative party, under Sir John Macdonald, began an agitation for Protection. This " national policy," as it was called, triumphed in 1879, ^"d, for the next ten years, Protection ran riot. Still, 220 THE CANADIAN PREFERENCE chap. our imports into Canada steadily increased, till, in 1885, a very severe tariff, directed, to all appear- ance, against our manufactures, was imposed, and the imports declined rapidly. In 1890, began a reaction against Protection, and, in 1896, Sir Wilfred Laurier came in on a programme of tariff reform. Protection, however, had now estab- lished the vested interest. In 1897, the Recipro- cal Tariff came into force. Rates were reduced, but not greatly reduced. The standard for the highest duties became 35 per cent, ad valorem. It was on this tariff that the first Preference of I2| per cent, on British goods was given. No reciprocal obligation on our part was ex- pected. Sir Wilfred Laurier stated, in so many words, that the Preference was not a quid pro quo; that Canada did not ask anything in return ; it was a recognition, he said, that the Canadians got in the home market of the Mother Country better treatment than in any of the foreign mar- kets of the world.^ In 1898, the Preference was increased to 25 per cent. But, under our treaties with certain foreign powers, it was found that the same pre- ference was claimed by Belgium, France, Germany, Spain, and many other countries. To remedy this, in July, 1898, we denounced these treaties as regards Belgium and Germany, and, in August of the same year, the Reciprocal Tariff was super- ^ According to Professor Flux, of Montreal, the Preference was given frankly for the benefit of the Canadian consumer, with no idea whatever of it being a sacrifice. — Economic Journal, Decem- ber, 1903. XXIII. ITS DISAPPOINTING RESULTS 221 seded by the British Preferential Tarifif, which gave 25 per cent, of reduction from the general tariff to Great Britain, Bermuda, West Indies, India, Ceylon, New South Wales, and the Straits Settlements.^ The Preference, how^ever, was not extended to all goods. Exception was made of Wines, Malt liquors. Spirits and Spirituous liquors, Medicines, articles containing Alcohol, Tobacco, Cigars, and Cigarettes. The average rate of duty on these is about 1 70 per cent, ad valorem. On 1st July, 1900, the Preference was raised ^o ZZh Ps*" cent, at which it still stands. Sir Charles Tupper, the Opposition leader, then took the definite position that a quid pro quo should be asked if the Preference were to be continued ; but Sir Wilfred Laurier held his ground that the Pre- ference was a free gift, and won with an un- diminished majority. The general results were summed up by Mr. Chamberlain at the Conference with the Colonial Premiers in 1902. In the five j^ears, our imports into Canada which came under the preference clause increased 5 5 per cent. But the general trade, that is the imports from foreign countries enjoying no preference, increased by 62 per cent. And the imports which came in free — that is, subject to no tariff and no prefer- ence — increased by 67 per cent. Or, taking it ' At the same time, the bounty on pig iron made from Canadian ores was raised from ^2 to $3 per ton, remaining at %z on that made from imported ores. As consequence, the production of pig iron rose from 58,000 tons in 1897 to 274,000 tons in 1901. 222 OUR EXPORTS INCREASED chap. another way, the total increase of the trade of Canada with foreigners was 69 per cent., while the total increase of British trade was only 48 per cent. This unlooked-for result calls for closer investigation. Canada has been passing through a time of extraordinary prosperity. In the last ten years, the country has been filling up. Foreign immigration has doubled. The great railways and the Hudson's Bay Company have been selling their lands rapidly. The Homestead entries have increased 150 per cent,, owing to the enormous influx of British settlers. Thousands of American farmers have crossed the border and become Canadians. And, among other phenomena, the foreign trade has doubled in seven years. It was to be expected, then, that British imports into Canada should have increased. But up till 1897 they were steadily falling. In 1882 and 1883, they were above £\o\ millions. In 1890, they were ;^8, 915,000; in 1896, -^6,776,000; in 1897, iJ^6,043,ooo. Succeeding years, how- ever, show as follows: 1898, - - 6,678,000 1899, - - 7,615,000 1900, - - 9,203,000 1901, - - 8,839,000 1902, - - 10,114,000 On the face of it, this seems very satisfactory. But a glance at the imports from other countries lessens the satisfaction. In the same period xxiii. BUT NOT PROPORTIONALLY 223 France has increased her sendings from i^ 5 34,000 in 1897 to ^1,371,000 in 1902. Germany has increased hers from i^i, 3 34,000 to i^2, 224,000. But the most suggestive figures are those of the United States. In 1 890, their imports into Canada were ;^ 10,744,000, and, in 1896, ;^i 2,035,000. The succeeding years show as follows : 1897, - - ;^I2,667,000 1898, - - 16,172,000 1899, - - 19,111,000 1900, - - 22,570,000 1901, - - 22,702,000 1902, - - 24,834,000^ The net result is that France's increase is 156 per cent; Germany's, 66 per cent.; America's, 96 per cent. ; while ours is only 6^ per cent. And although France and Germany started from a low figure, and a percentage com- parison between their increase and ours is there- fore not sound argument,'^ this is not the case with '^Colonial Statistical Abstract, 1903, p. 210. The figures in- clude bullion and specie. 2 A more detailed comparison with other countries brings out much more startling results when stated in percentages. For in- stance, in the same six years, Holland increased her sendings to Canada by 133 per cent. ; Switzerland, 148 per cent. ; Portugal, 184 per cent. ; South America, other than British Guiana, 194 per cent. ; Italy, 223 per cent. But, as starting from compara- tively small amounts, these are not adequate, but only suggestive comparisons. How, in face of these figures, it could be said that " the increase in our trade with Canada has been very great, but // has not increased largely out of proportion to the increase of the trade between Canada and other countries," passes my compre- hension. 224 EXPLANATION OF FAILURE chap. America, which started from a higher level. It would be difficult to draw an argument for the success of a Preference from figures like these. The explanation of our failure, however, is not far to seek. What determines imports into a country is not cheapness alone, but demand. Canada wants our whisky because Canada likes it, so our exports of whisky increase although we get no preference, and although all whisky is subject to a duty of $2.40 per gallon, Canada finds the agricultural implements of America more suitable for her soil, so she imports them, although the duty on our implements is one- third less. Again, in judging of the effects of a tariff in keeping out the goods of a particular country, it is not the average rates of duty that have to be considered, but the rates on the goods which that country sends. There are certain things admitted free into Canada, such as anthracite, coal and coke, raw cotton, crude rubber, rough sawn timber, undressed hemp, fur skins, hides, steel rails. 70 per cent, of these free imports come from the United States — for obvious reasons — and this free entry does not do us much good. Raw materials, again, of iron, steel, leather, and wood, and many agricultural products, are ad- mitted at comparatively low rates. Here, again, the advantage America has over us is obvious. The heaviest duties are on textiles — woollens, cottons, silks, and linens. These are the goods we wish to send into Canada, and these are the XXIII. ''ALTOGETHER DISAPPOINTING" 225 goods which the Canadian consumer would very gladly take from us. But they are also the goods which Canada is bent on manufacturing for herself, and here, allowing for the preference, we have to pass our textiles through an actual rate of 23-^ per cent. The rivalry, in fact, which concerns us is not that between foreign countries — particularly the United States — and ourselves for the Canadian trade, but the rivalry between the Canadian manufacturer and the British manufacturer. There is little wonder, then, that the result of the Preference was pronounced " altogether dis- appointing." " The tariff still presses with the greatest severity on Canada's best customer, and has favoured the foreigner." As Mr. Chamber- lain put it to the Colonial Premiers at the Con- ference : " So long as a preferential tariff is still sufficiently protective to exclude us altogether, or nearly so, from your markets, it is no satisfaction to us that you have imposed even greater dis- ability upon the same goods if they come from foreign markets, especially if the articles in which the foreigners are interested come in under more favourable conditions." If England cannot get in at the front door, it is small consolation that America is kept at the garden gate. It would not be reasonable to say that, in this comparative failure, we have an argument against Preference. It might have been the case that, but for it, our exports to Canada would have gone on declining, while those of the countries which had no Preference increased. All that can p 226 IS IT WORTH A SACRIFICE? CH. xxill. be said is that it is impossible to see in it any great argument for a Preference where the cir- cumstances are similar. It must be remembered, however, that the Canadian Preference, such as it is, is a free gift. We gave no quid pro quo : we made no sacrifice. But how, in face of this failure, can any British statesman ask his fellow-countrymen to make a sacrifice ? Suppose we shut out the foreigner from our market, in order to admit Canada free, how will this help us to get into her' market? She admits us at a third less than our rivals now, and we cannot make headway. How shall we be any more able to enter by giving her a Preference on our imports ? The expectation seems to be that, by doing so, we shall induce her to increase the amount of her Preference to us. But she has declared, in unequivocal terms, that this is what she will, on no consideration, do.^ Whether it be from want of humour on her part, or from under-estimation of our common sense, all she does is to hint that she might raise her tariff higher against the rest of the world. Neither we nor our rivals can climb the thirty foot wall ; to favour us, however, she will raise it to forty feet against them ! ^ In his Budget speech of April, 1903, Mr. Fielden said that any change they made might favour Great Britain against the foreign competitor — "not over the Canadian manufacturer." CHAPTER XXIV. OUR POSSIBLE GAIN FROM COLONIAL PREFERENCE. When we deduct ittiports we could not send, and imports we cannot in reason hope to send, the amount of trade which we might possibly take from the foreigner is quite insignificant. The above, then, being the actual results of the Canadian Preference, the next consideration is as to what would be the possible gain to us from a preference system adopted by all the self-govern- ing Colonies, What we have to do evidently is to ask how much foreign countries send into these Colonies at present, and see how much of that trade we could take from them under such a system.^ According to the last returns, June, 1901, Canada imported from outside (exclusive of bullion and specie) goods to the value of ^^3 8,400,000. Of this, ;i^8, 8 29,000, or 23 per cent, came from the United Kingdom; ^^^76 1,000, or 2 per cent, came from British Possessions; .^28,810,000, or 75 per cent., came from Foreign Countries. ^ The details which follow are taken from the Board of Trade Blue Book, p. 381. 228 OUR POSSIBLE GAIN FROM chap. What we may possibly gain is some of the trade represented by the ^28,810,000. But, from this possibility we must deduct : — (i) Goods which Great Britain does not grow or make, such as Sugar, £\.6 millions; Maize, £\.1 millions; Raw Cotton and Cotton Wool, ;^98 1,000 ; Tea, ^^463,000 ; Rubber, ;^363,ooo ; Tobacco, i!^349,ooo ; Green Fruit, ;!^347,ooo ; Dried Fruits, ^256,000, etc., etc. Such goods make up a total of ^^6,273,000 of imports into Canada which we could not take from the foreigner. (2) Many goods we do grow or make, but could not, in reason, hope to supply Canada with — they are almost all United States products — such as Coal and Coal dust, ^2,737,000 ; Wheat, ;^i, 309,000; Wood, ;£^687,ooo; Oats, i^i 95,000; Bacon and Hams, ^149,000; Coke, i^ 140,000; Horses, i^ 12 5, 000; Cheese, ;^ 12 5,000; Pork, ;^94,ooo, etc., etc. These make up a total of ;^6, 583,000. Deducting these two items, there is left ^16 millions of imports into Canada which we might possibly take from foreign nations and secure for our own producers. But we have had a Prefer- ence since 1897, and we are further away from getting any of it than ever. What new induce- ment is there for our exporters to do any more than they are doing ? Or what new inducement is there for the Canadian consumer to demand that these goods be British-made and not foreign- made? But, on looking into the details of the XXIV. EXTENSION OF THE PREFERENCE 229 £\6 millions, we find something more that makes the possibility still less of a probability. It is that these foreign imports are scattered over some seventy categories of different goods, only one of them amounting to over a million. Is it to be expected that seventy different trades, without any new motive, will show enough new energy and enterprise to wrest these imports from the foreigner ? Pursuing the same line of investigation as regards the other self-governing Colonies, we get the following results : Cape Colony, in 1900, imported from outside iTi;, 163,000. Of this, i^i 1,053,000, or 64^ per cent., came from the United Kingdom ; ;^2, 478,000, or 14! per cent, came from British Possessions; ;^3,63 2,000, or 21 per cent., came from Foreign Countries. The possible gain of trade for us is ,^2,092,000, spread over some forty categories, only five of them over iJ" 100,000. New Zealand, in 1900, imported from outside ;^io,2o8,ooo. Of this, i^6,45 3,000, or 6t^ per cent., came from the United Kingdom; i^2, 239,000, or 22 per cent, came from British Possessions; ;^i,5 16,000, or 15 per cent, came from Foreign Countries. The possible gain is i^ 1,2 76,000, spread over some forty-five categories, only three of them over ;^6o,ooo. Australia, in 1900, imported from outside i;40,i 88,000. Of this, ^^25,113,000, or 63 per cent, came from the United Kingdom ; .^{^3,728,000, or 9 per cent, came from British 230 OUR POSSIBLE GAIN chap. Possessions; ;^i 1,347,000, or 28 per cent, came from Foreign Countries. The possible gain is ;i^8, 007,000, spread over some seventy categories, only five of them over .^^250,000. Natal, in 1900, imported from outside ;^5,9i2,ooo. Of this, ^3,726,000, or 63 per cent, came from the United Kingdom; i^ 1,1 47,000, or 19 per cent., came from British Possessions ; iS^ 1, 03 9,000, or 18 per cent, came from Foreign Countries. The possible gain is ;^5 39,000, spread over twenty categories, only two of them over ;^6o,ooo. Newfoundland, in 1900, imported from out- side ;^i,5i2,ooo. Of this, ;^45 8,000, or 30 per cent., came from the United Kingdom ; ;^5 82,000, or 39 per cent, came from British Possessions; ;^47 2,000, or 31 per cent, came from Foreign Countries. The possible gain is iJ^2 20,000, spread over twenty categories, only two of them over ;^20,ooo. The total is : — Canada, - - - i^i 5,954,000 Australia, - - - 8,007,000 Cape Colony, - - 2,092,000 New Zealand, - - 1,276,000 Natal, - - - - 539,000 Newfoundland, - - 220,000 ;^28,o88,ooo That is the magnificent total possibility ; the limit of our possible extension of trade if we could secure the whole of the Colonial imports XXIV. /S SOME i\2 MILLIONS 231 which foreign countries now send.^ If we deduct the Canadian £\6 millions on which we have a Preference, there remain £\2 millions which we might possibly take from the foreigner by the extension of the preference system over all our Colonies. But the probability, of course, is ever so much less. In this list are numbers of things that the Colonies will not take from us, even if they are cheaper than competing goods from other countries : we have seen how it is with Canada — that what determines an import is not so much cheapness as a demand for a special quality or style of article.- We should be well off if we gained a quarter of the £\2 millions. If this possible but extremely improbable in- crease of trade were the sole ground for overturn- ing our Free Trade system, and establishing tariffs against countries which send us some three-fourths of the goods we import, then one would be inclined to say that nothing so reckless and ill- judged had ever been proposed in the British Parliament.-'^ ^ It is perhaps unnecessary to remind the reader that this sum of £z%,ooo, 170, 173, 181. 190, 206. Gifts, as Imports, 26. Gladstone, W. E., 217. Glasgow, 102. Gold, in payments, 11-12, 14, 16, 42, 192-193- Grey, Earl, 250. Grey, Sir Edward, 211. Guyot, Yves, 74. Hamilton, Alexander, 56. Holland, 15, 124, 153, 205. Hours of Labour, 177, 201-202, 264. Immorality, Political, 90-91 ; Commercial, 91-92. Imports, of United Kingdom, 8 ; Excess of, 15, 17-27, 41; Equivalence of Exports and, 28-35, 42-44 ; Duties on, 16, 46-47, 98. Income Tax, 39, 40, 98, 108, 113, 132, 156, 172-173- Income, National, 213. Index Numbers, 191. India, 23, 145, 218. Infant Industry Argument, 56- 60, 65, loi, 112. Insurance, 18, 21. Investments, Foreign and Colo- nial, 22, 27, 29, 37-39, 251 ; Municipal, 102, 180-181. Iron. See Steel. Italy, 15, 24, 25, 126, 194, 205. Japan, 15, 62, 194, 195, 279. Jevons, W. S., 187, 191. Kartell. See Trusts. Laurier, Sir Wilfred, 220, 221, 250. Lawson, 7. Life, the end of Production, 2-5. Linen, 8. List, Friedrich, 56. Loans. See Investments. Machinery, Exports of, 8. Manufactures, Taxation of, 86-88, 137-138. INDEX 283 Marshall, Alfred, 212, 265-266. Matheson, Ewing, 35. Mill, J. S., 58,209. M'Kinley, President, 69. M 'Master, Professor, 64. Morley, John, 267. Most Favoured Nation Clause, 127-128, I34-I5S- Municipal Enterprise, 41. Napoleon, 49, 61, 64, 190. Navigation Act, 216. New Zealand, 217, 229, 236, 256. Norway, 5, 15, 194. Oldham, C. H., 159. Parker, Sir Gilbert, 246. Pauperism, 170- 171. Pauper Labour Argument, 70. Payment in Trade, 11-14. Peel, Sir Robert, 120, 125, 216, 243- Percentages, Fallacy of, 194-195. Political Influence, 73,74, 90-91. Portugal, 15, 194. Preferential Tariffs, 216-2 18, 227- 244; Canadian, 219-226; and Agriculture, 245-248 ; and Empire, 249-259. Prices, Changes of, 171- 172, 191-194. Profit, the motive of Trade, 10, 33- Prosperity, Tests of, 170-178; and Exports, 179-185. Protection, Meaning of, 47 ; as Prohibition, 69 ; as National Policy, 50-51, 219; against Cheapness, 53-55, 92 ; as Ap- prenticeship, 57 ; Historical, 60-66, 67-68. Rabbeno, U., 66. Raw Materials, 78-85, 137, 177-201, 236. Reciprocity, 120. See Preferen- tial Tariffs. Retaliation, 1 18-143; on Dump- ing, 160-169. Revenge, 11 8- 1 19. Ricardo, J. L. , 124. Roosevelt, President, 69. Ruskin, John, 119. Russia, 16, 125, 139, 205. Sauerbeck's Index Number, 191. Savings, National, 36, 173-175. Services, 1-4, 17-27. Shakespeare, W., 48. Shearman, T. G., 106. Shipping, 8, 9, 17-20, 28, 33, 40, 63, 176, 272, 275-280. Ships, 5, 8, 26, 152-153- Sidgwick, H., 58. Smith, Adam, 16, 61, 84, 118, 124. Spain, 5, 15, 16. Steel, 5, 8, 116, 144, 149, 152- 158, 163, 180. Steel Trust, 60, 150, 158-159, 166, 183. Sugar Convention, 131, I45j_i5i.. Sumner, W. G., 69, 88, 114. Sweden, 15. Switzerland, 24, 81, 126. Tariff, shuts in home goods, 42-43 ; Complex, 68, 89 ; Principle of, 69-75 '■> Scien- tific, 76-88; Injury of, II9- 121, 133, 142. See Preferential Tariffs, Retaliation. Taussig, F. W., 66. Taxation, a Price, 93, 97, 99 ; for Revenue, 46-47, 77 ; for Protection, 47,69,75-93-117, 132, 237-244; Indirect, 98, 109, 113. See Income Tax. Thomas, D. A., 203. Tools, 86-S7. Trade, Nature of, 1-6. Trade Current, 28. Trade, Foreign. See Foreign Trade. Trade Unions, 4, 70, 175, 271. 'Triangular Exchange,' 35. Trusts, loi, 146-149, 158-159, 161, 166, 182, 263. See Steel Trust. Tupper, Sir Charles, 60, 221. 284 INDEX United States. See America. Uruguay, i6. Venice, 19. Vested Interests, 60, 62-66, 88, 140-142. Wages, 171, 204, 264 ; in America, 69-70 ; in Germany, 172. Walsh, C. M., 191. Wheat, 8, 32, 34, 144, 237-244. Wool, Imports of, 8, 79, 82, 255. Woollens, Exports of, 8, 168. _^;rr;>-)0TrTP^,^^ n.' GLASGOW : PRINTEU AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS BY ROBERT MACLEHOSE AND CO. LTD. "I i T TT7IO ^mr r,. GENERAL LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA— BERKELEY RETURN TO DESK FROM WHICH BORROWED This book is due on the last date stamped below, or on the date to which renewed. Renewed books are subject to immediate recall. ''^'^^4^A f^ St 4P/? ^3 1954 ^ ^ 1955 0V8 1954 LU LD 21-100m-l,'54(1887sl6)476 ^>^ w^ YC 05603 y .-./At- '^■'V. •:-i<-: .:/v^^r^ 't-^'^irajf^ ,9^. y^t :y^}:"-4 ■■''%i:^$ _-;'^-->*f! .-SlS