\ 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 The Economic Aspects of European 
 Immigration to the United States 
 
 By 
 Isaac A. Hourwich, Ph.D. 
 
 Second Edition 
 Revised 
 
 New York 
 B. W. HUEBSCH, 
 
 1922 
 
COPYRIGHT, 1912 
 
 BY 
 G. P. PUTNAM'S SONS 
 
 COPYRIGHT. 1923 
 
 BY 
 
 ISAAC A. HOURWICH, PH.D. 
 
 Printed by Harper & Brother* 
 New York 
 
PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION 
 
 IMMIGRATION is treated in this book solely as an eco- 
 1 nomic question. In this the author followed the Immi- 
 gration Commission, which was created by Congress in 1907, 
 and presented its report in 1910. He was not unaware of 
 the existence of a sentiment against immigration, based upon 
 other than economic considerations. Indeed, most of the 
 first chapter, and a part of the third, are devoted to this 
 aspect of the question. But he concurs in the opinion of the 
 experts of the Immigration Commission, and of the Com- 
 mission on Industrial Relations, that the objections to im- 
 migration are fundamentally of an economic nature^ Prior 
 to the war, the only real power behind the agitation in favor 
 of restriction of immigration was organized labor. Our 
 statesmen in Washington took scant notice of the academic 
 disquisitions in the domains of anthropology, ethnology, 
 sociology, eugenics, and political science, which presented 
 the old arguments of the Know-Nothings dressed up in a 
 modern scientific garb. But they listened to union officials 
 who proposed to reward their friends and punish their 
 enemies on election "day. Yet the opposition of labor to 
 immigration was outweighed by the influence of capital, 
 which regarded free trade in the labor market as indispensable 
 for the expansion of American industry. The social revolu- 
 tion in Russia and its echoes in Hungary, Germany, and 
 Italy, as well as the growth of the Socialist and Communist 
 parties in all European countries, have aroused a fear of 
 immigration among American capitalists. Labor and capital 
 now united in the demand for restrictive legislation. Or- 
 ganized labor favofta "complete exclusion of immigration, 
 capital favored a "selective \\test meant to bar all immi- 
 
 iii 
 
/V tPr-efctce to the Second Edition 
 
 '" Bolshevism," which is a comprehensive 
 term for every variety of economic and political heresy. A 
 compromise was reached by the passage of the recent immi- 
 gration act, supplemented by the order of the State De- 
 partment requiring the visaing of the passports of all in- 
 tending immigrants by American consuls in the countries 
 of emigration. Both are merely emergency measures, and 
 the matter will again be before Congress at its regular 
 session. The object of this edition is to aid in the public 
 discussion of this question. 
 
 The first edition of this book appeared less than two years 
 before the World War. No changes in the structure of 
 society manifest themselves within two years under ordinary 
 conditions. No new immigration legislation was enacted 
 during that time. It is, therefore, reasonable to assume that 
 the normal effects of immigration on the eve of the war 
 were the same as at the time when this book was first pub- 
 lished. The outbreak of the European war produced a 
 revolutionary change. As an ardent advocate of restriction 
 exultingly put it, "the war did to immigration what all the 
 restrictionist agitation in the world could not have accom- 
 plished it stopped it altogether." 1 Here was an opportunity 
 to test the effects of the cessation of immigration upon the 
 condition of labor in the United States. This subject is 
 treated in the new chapter, "The Lessons of the War," 
 dealing with labor conditions during the late war. The 
 forecast of the probable effects of restriction of immigration, 
 which was the concluding chapter of the first edition, has 
 been retained, with the omission of the discussion of some of 
 the recommendations of the Immigration Commission which 
 are now out of date. The reader is thus enabled to verify 
 the deductions drawn from the history of immigration prior 
 to the war, by the experience of labor during a period without 
 immigration. The new chapter may serve as an answer to 
 the main criticisms of the first edition. 
 A reviewer in The Quarterly Journal of Economics scouted 
 1 Prof. Henry P. Fairchild in The New York Times of October 12, 1919. 
 
Preface to the Second Edition v 
 
 the "elaborate treatment . . . accorded the question 'has 
 emigration from Southern and Eastern Europe checked emi 
 gration from Northern and Western Europe?'" It seemed 
 to him that "restrictionists ... who plan and expect a re- 
 vival of the older immigration, are not conspicuous." Yet 
 this is the avowed aim of the 3 per cent quota of the immi- 
 gration law which was enacted last spring. 
 
 A detailed analysis of the points raised by critics will be 
 found in the Appendix. 
 
 ISAAC A. HOURWICH. 
 NEW YORK, September 15, 1921. 
 
 PREFACE TO THE FIRST EDITION 
 
 THE Immigration Commission, after three years of 
 investigation, reached the conclusion that our immi- 
 gration policy "should be based primarily upon economic or 
 business considerations." ' This conclusion has determined 
 the scope of the present book: it treats immigration solely 
 as an economic question. For the same reason the dis- 
 cussion is confined to European immigration, Oriental 
 immigration being viewed by many students primarily as 
 a race question, which reaches out beyond the domain of 
 economics. 
 
 The author gratefully acknowledges his indebtedness to 
 Mr. William W. Bishop, superintendent of the Reading 
 Room, Library of Congress, who obligingly placed at his 
 disposal the exceptional facilities of the Library; to Mr. 
 W. W. Husband, secretary of the Immigration Commission, 
 who courteously gave him access to the proof sheets of the 
 reports of the Commission, in advance of their publication; 
 and to the young men and women who assisted him in the 
 
 preparation of the material for this book. 
 
 I. A. rl. 
 
 WASHINGTON, D. C., July 23, 1912- 
 
CONTENTS 
 PART I. 
 
 SUMMARY REVIEW. 
 
 PACK 
 
 Difference between the old and the new immigration quantitative, 
 
 not qualitative. ..... ! 
 
 Immigration and emigration regulated by demand for labor . . 3 
 
 The myth of imported immigrants 2 
 
 Unemployment the result of industrial maladjustment . . 4 
 Unemployment varies inversely with immigration . . . 5 
 Limited demand for immigrant labor in agriculture ... 7 
 Effect of immigration not racial displacement, but evolution of 
 
 an English-speaking aristocracy of labor .... 9 
 Causes of the decrease of emigration from Northern and Western 
 
 Europe 13 
 
 Race suicide unrelated to immigration . . . . .18 
 Economic reason for the predominance of unskilled laborers among 
 
 the immigrants i 
 
 The standard of living of the recent immigrant not inferior to that 
 
 of his predecessors 19 
 
 Higher standard of living of the American workman maintained 
 
 with the aid of his children's wages 22 
 
 Native workmen and older immigrants not underbid by recent 
 
 immigrants 23 
 
 Employment of immigrants in large numbers going together with 
 
 advances in wages 24^, 
 
 Reduction of child labor in States with a large immigrant popu- 
 lation. Child labor a substitute for immigration . . 26 
 
 Reduction of the workday 27 
 
 Work accidents not the result of immigration .... 29 
 Immigration and trade-unionism. Union membership rising and 
 
 falling with the rise and fall of immigration . 30 
 
 Organization among the unskilled 3 2 
 
 Regulation of terms of employment by conferences between organ- 
 ized capital and organized labor . 33 
 vi i 
 
J 
 
 viii Contents 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Immigration not the cause of the labor problem . . -34 
 Restriction of immigration no relief for unemployment . . 35 
 The lesson of the late war; decline of real wages amidst industrial 
 
 prosperity, in the absence of immigration . 36 
 
 PART II. 
 
 TOPICAL ANALYSIS. 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 STATEMENT OF THE QUESTION. 
 
 Objections to immigration 40 
 
 Old and new immigration 41 
 
 What is "undesirable" immigration 41 
 
 The problem of assimilation 42 
 
 Restriction of competition demanded by organized labor . . 44 
 
 Cosmopolitanism and the theory of "seclusion and isolation" . 45 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 THE REPORT OF THE IMMIGRATION COMMISSION. 
 
 Conclusions of the Commission: Immigration an economic 
 
 problem 48' 
 
 Defects of the Report: 
 
 Absence of a historical view 50 
 
 Lack of statistical evidence to support its conclusions . 51 
 
 Race distinction the dominant idea of the investigation . 55 
 Deceptive statistical generalizations . . i . . .58 
 
 CHAPTER III. k 
 
 OLD AND NEW IMMIGRATION. 
 
 The immigrant of bygone days as popularly pictured . 61 
 The bulk of immigrants a century ago indentured servants . 62 
 Destitution of the free immigrants before the era of the "new 
 
 immigration" 63 
 
 Congestion in the settlements of past generations of immi- 
 grants in New York City . .- . . .65 
 Aversion of the early Irish immigrants to employment in 
 
 farming 67 
 
Contents 
 
 IX 
 
 PACK 
 
 Majority of the old immigration unskilled laborers ... 67 
 Percentage of skilled mechanics about the same for the last 
 
 half century 69 
 
 No evidence of a lowered standard of immigration ... 69 
 The average immigrant intellectually above the average of his 
 
 countrymen at home 70 
 
 Social prejudice against immigrants in the past 73 
 
 The "bird of passage" .74 
 
 The problem of assimilation . 75 
 
 Opposition of organized labor antedates the "new immigration" 78 
 
 Note: The Statistics of Italian Illiteracy.^, 80 
 
 CHAPTER/IV^ 1r 
 
 f IMMIGRATION AND THE LABOR MARKET. 
 
 Demand for labor increasing faster than population ... 82 
 
 Immigration follows business conditions 86 
 
 How the volume of immigration is regulated .... 93 
 
 Importation of contract laborers infrequent .... 99 
 
 Character of immigration determined by demand for labor . 101 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 THE DEMAND FOR LABOR IN AGRICULTURE. 
 
 Relative and absolute decrease of the rural population . .103 
 Migration of Americans of native stock to the city . . .104 
 Comparative demand for labor in agriculture and industry . 104 
 Differentiation of manufacturing from farming . . .106 
 
 Centralization of industry and its effect upon farming . .107 
 
 Introduction of labor-saving machinery 108 
 
 Displacement of the wage-earner IO 9 
 
 Low wages . . . . no 
 
 Long hours IIQ 
 
 Limits to further growth of agricultural population . . .112 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 UNEMPLOYMENT. 
 
 A. The Causes of Unemployment. 
 
 Unemployment not the result of over-population . . "4 
 Differentiation of manufacturing from farming leads to un- 
 employment . . 1*4 
 
x Contents 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Seasonal trade variations 115 
 
 Lack of mobility of skilled labor 117 
 
 Cyclical fluctuations of employment 121 
 
 Dissipation of the demand for labor 121 
 
 The labor reserve 124 
 
 B. Unemployment and Immigration. 
 
 Native and foreign-born workmen equally affected by un- 
 employment 125 
 
 Unemployment is in inverse ratio to the relative number of 
 
 foreign-born 128 
 
 Annual variations of the relative number unemployed . 137 
 Annual variations of the number of working days . .140 
 
 Immigration not a contributory cause of unemployment . 145 
 
 A remedy against unemployment 146 
 
 CHAPTER VII. 
 
 RACIAL STRATIFICATION. 
 
 Migratory character of the population of the United States . 148 
 Industrial growth of the country west of the Atlantic Seaboard 
 
 States 150 
 
 Adjustment of native and foreign elements on the scale of 
 
 occupations 150 
 
 Actual displacement of American wage-earners by immigrants a 
 
 rare exception ........ 151 
 
 Extraordinary expansion of the iron and steel industry. Native 
 
 Americans employed in increased numbers since immigration 
 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe has become conspicuous. 158 
 Economic opportunity for the advancement of English-speaking 
 
 wage-earners created by immigration . . . .161 
 "Racial displacement" a negligible quantity . ' . . .165 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 EMIGRATION FROM NORTHERN AND WESTERN EUROPE. 
 
 A. Introductory: Emigration from Northern and Western 
 Europe cannot keep pace with the demand for immigrant 
 labor in the United States ... .177 
 
 B. Germany. 
 
 Excess of immigration to, over emigration from Germany . 180 
 Sources of immigration to Germany: Southern and Eastern 
 
 Europe 181 
 
Contents xi 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Industrial expansion j8 2 
 
 Increased demand for labor . . . . .185 
 
 Improvement of the condition of labor . . . .185 
 
 Progress of labor legislation . . . . . .188 
 
 Agricultural progress. Advance in the wages of farm labor. 189 
 Co-operation ......... 191 
 
 Effects of the repeal, in 1890, of the exceptional laws of 
 
 1878 191 
 
 Immigration of German unskilled laborers to the United 
 States has increased with the increasing tide of immi- 
 gration from Southern and Eastern Europe . . . 192 
 
 C. The Scandinavians. 
 
 Immigration of Scandinavian breadwinners to the United 
 
 States highest in 1901-1910 196 
 
 Scandinavians seeking employment in competition with im- 
 migrants from Southern and Eastern Europe . . 198 
 
 D. Norway. 
 
 Total number of Norwegian immigrants highest in 1901-1910 202 
 Recent industrial development of Norway . . . 202 
 
 E. Denmark. 
 
 Conditions of the Danish peasants greatly improved since 
 
 theSo's. Success of agricultural co-operation . . 203 
 
 Polish migration to Denmark 204 
 
 Progress of the manufacturing industry. Strong organization 
 
 oflabor 204 
 
 P. Sweden. 
 
 Cause of the decline of emigration from rural districts: Small 
 
 demand for farm help in the United States . . 205 
 
 Immigration to Sweden 206 
 
 Recent industrial development 207 
 
 Progress of organized labor 208 
 
 G. The United Kingdom. 
 
 Development of the British colonies drawing immigrants from 
 
 the mother country 209 
 
 Effect of colonial restriction of foreign immigration . 210 
 Encouragement of immigration of British subjects by the 
 
 Canadian and the Australian Governments . .210 
 Emigration from the British Isles to the United States in 
 
 1880-1909 not below normal. Rising tide in 1898-1907 . 211 
 Improvement of living conditions in Great Britain . . 2i4 
 
xii Contents 
 
 FAGB 
 
 H. Ireland. 
 
 Emigration from Ireland decreasing since 1860 . . .215 
 
 Effects of land reform 217 
 
 Welfare work of the country governments . . . .218 
 The co-operative movement . . . . . .218 
 
 Rise in wages of farm laborers 218 
 
 Improvement of the condition of the people . . .219 
 
 /. Conclusion: Immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 could not be replaced by immigration from Northern and 
 Western Europe 220 
 
 CHAPTER IX. 
 
 RACE SUICIDE. 
 
 General Walker's explanation of the decline in the native birth- 
 rate: Native stock replaced by immigration . . .221 
 Decline of the birth-rate begins in 1810-1830 .... 223 
 
 A world-wide phenomenon 224 
 
 Race suicide universal among social classes not affected by im- 
 migrant competition 224 
 
 CHAPTER X. 
 
 THE STANDARD OF LIVING. 
 
 A. Introductory: The subject of inquiry comparative stand- 
 
 ards of unskilled laborers, past and present . . . 228 
 
 B. Congestion in New York City. 
 
 Overcrowding and filth in the first half of the past century . 229 
 Squalid rooms of native American sewing women . .231 
 
 The shanty dwellers in the middle of the nineteenth century 231 
 
 The Irish and German colonies in the 60 's . . . 232 
 Improved conditions of the Jewish and Italian districts of 
 
 our day 234 
 
 Industrial causes of congestion 235 
 
 Effect of congestion upon cost of living and wages . . 240 
 
 C. Housing Conditions in the Country at Large. 
 
 Housing conditions of New England working girls in the 40*3 . 241 
 Filthy and unsanitary tenements in Boston in the days of the 
 
 old immigration . . . . . . .241 
 The same conditions in smaller towns .... 243 
 Shanty dwellers in Massachusetts 244 
 
Contents xiii 
 
 PACK 
 
 Comparison with housing conditions in Ireland . . 245 
 
 Housing conditions of native white unskilled laborers in 
 
 Southern mill towns ...... 246 
 
 Cause of bad housing conditions economic, not racial . . 247 
 Responsibility of the landlords . . . . . 247 
 
 Company houses 248 
 
 Tendency of the Immigration Commission to shift the blame 
 
 to the tenant ........ 249 
 
 Fallacy of the race classification adopted by the Commission . 250 
 Rental paid by immigrants as high as, or higher than, that 
 
 paid by native wage-earners . . . . . 250 
 Native American wage-earners in small towns with low rents 
 
 able to underbid the immigrant workers of large cities 
 
 with high rents 255 
 
 D. Food: Existence of a race standard of living not proved . 256 
 
 E. Clothing. 
 
 Prices paid by recent immigrants the same as those paid by 
 
 native Americans ....... 265 
 
 Race variations insignificant 266 
 
 F. Savings. 
 
 Small margin of income left for savings . . . .. 267 
 American wage-earners not injured by the investments of 
 
 immigrants in their home countries .... 269 
 
 The Mercantilist objection to the exportation of money . 271 
 
 CHAPTER XL 
 
 HOME OWNERSHIP. 
 
 Point of view of the Immigration Commission not that of the 
 
 wage-earner 2 74 
 
 Irregularity of employment a bar to home ownership . . 274 
 
 Handicap in labor disputes . 2 7 6 
 
 Tenancy in Boston in 1790, 1845, 1890, and 1900 . .^ . 276 
 Native home owners before the period of the "new immi- 
 gration" 
 
 Home ownership decreasing with the increase of land values . 278 
 Immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe not long enough 
 
 in the United States to have acquired homes 
 Tenancy increasing with the growth of urban population . . 282 
 
xiv Contents 
 
 CHAPTER XII. 
 
 EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES. 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Difference in wages due to grade of service, not to country of 
 
 birth 284 
 
 Native American and Americanized families maintain a higher 
 
 standard with the aid of children's earnings . . . 285 
 Recently -landed immigrants not engaged at less than the prevail- 
 ing rates of wages 285 
 
 Machinery and immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe. 28$ 
 
 Defects of wage statistics . . . . . . 292 
 
 Wages in urban and rural manufactures: Country competition 
 
 of native Americans tends to lower the wages of immigrants 297 
 
 Rates of wages not affected by immigration .... 299 
 
 Increase of wages result of industrial expansion . . . 302 
 
 Wages of railroad employees 302 
 
 Low salaries of clerical help 304 
 
 Wages in coal mines and steel mills 305 
 
 What would have been the increase of wages without immigration 
 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe? .... 306 
 
 Wages of older employees kept up by immigration from Southern 
 
 and Eastern Europe . 309 
 
 x CHAPTER XIII. 
 
 HOURS OF LABOR. 
 
 Hours of labor of native American mill hands in the ante-immi- 
 gration period 311 
 
 Reduction of hours contemporaneous with immigration . . 313 
 Foreign unskilled laborers in the steel industry working shorter 
 hours than English-speaking skilled and semi-skilled em- 
 ployees 314 
 
 Reduction of the working day in the cotton mills . . .315 
 Comparative reduction of hours in New York City and in the 
 
 remainder of New York State, 1901-1910 .... 315 
 
 CHAPTER XIV. * 
 
 CHILD LABOR. 
 
 Child labor in the early days of the factory system . . . 318 
 Decrease in the employment of children contemporaneous with in- 
 crease of immigration 318 
 
Contents xv 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Employment of children in the South relatively greater than in 
 
 States with a large immigrant population . . . .319 
 Child labor in rural Missouri 322 
 
 CHAPTER XV. f 
 
 LABOR ORGANIZATIONS. 
 
 Conclusions of the Immigration Commission contradicted by its 
 statistics: Trade union affiliation of Jewish and Italian cloth- 
 ing workers in New York City above the average for the 
 
 wage-earners of the country at large 325 
 
 Membership in labor unions unaffected by race . . . 326 
 Organization among immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe as strong as among natives and immigrants from 
 
 Northern and Western Europe 327 
 
 Labor unions previous to 1880 ephemeral .... 329 
 Greatest progress coincides with the great tide of immigration of 
 
 the last decade 330 
 
 Union membership in New York State rising and falling with 
 
 rise and fall of immigration 335 
 
 Trade-unionism stronger in New York than in Kansas with its 
 
 decreasing foreign-born population 337 
 
 Trade unions stronger in New York City than in the remainder 
 
 of the State . . .341 
 
 Strikes increasing with immigration 343 
 
 Trade unions mostly confined to skilled crafts. Unskilled laborers 
 
 not eligible for membership in craft unions . . . 34 6 
 Discrimination against immigrants . . . . . . 347 
 
 Conflicting interests of the skilled and the unskilled . . -347 
 
 Example of the Lawrence strike 34^ 
 
 Possibilities of organization among the unskilled . . . 349 
 Home training of immigrants in organization . r . . . 349 
 
 Effect of machinery upon craft unions 35 1 
 
 Trusts against unions 35 2 
 
 CHAPTER XVI. 
 
 PAUPERISM AND CRIME. 
 
 A. Introductory: The period of the greatest immigration at- 
 
 tended by a decrease of pauperism and crime . . 353 
 
 B. Pauperism. 
 
 Pauperism less frequent among the new immigration than 
 
 among the old. . 354 
 
xvi Contents 
 
 Difference not due to "racial displacement. " 
 Pauperism the result of industrial invalidism 
 C. Crime. 
 
 Supposed criminal proclivities of the foreigner: Popular 
 
 prejudice unfounded ... 
 
 Increase of immigration coincident with decrease of crime. 
 
 PART III. 
 IMMIGRANTS IN THE LEADING INDUSTRIES. 
 
 CHAPTER XVII. 
 
 THE GARMENT WORKERS. 
 
 Origin of the sweating system antedates immigration 
 
 Real wages of sewing women of past generations lower than 
 
 to-day. Long hours in the past 
 
 Competition of farm-house labor in the middle of the nineteenth 
 
 century . .... 
 
 Expansion of the clothing industry the result of immigration 
 Introduction of the factory system followed by increase of wages. 
 Rates of wages not influenced by racial factors 
 Earnings of recent immigrant women higher than those of native 
 
 Americans . . 
 
 American garment workers in the country accepting a lower rate of 
 
 wages than Jewish city workers .... 
 Organization among clothing workers more effective than among 
 
 other industrial workers in the United States 
 
 CHAPTER XVIII. 
 
 THE COTTON MILLS. 
 
 Wages in 1875-1908: intermittent advances and reductions prior 
 to the "new immigration"; upward movement since. 
 
 Effect of immigration on organization of labor .... 
 
 No competition between union labor and unorganized immigrants. 
 In labor contests immigrants have supported the unions. 
 
 Competition of the Southern mills: Cheap white labor of the 
 South keeping down the wages of immigrants in the North. 
 
 CHAPTER XIX. 
 
 THE WOOLEN MILLS. 
 The Lawrence strike and public opinion . . . 
 
Contents xvii 
 
 MM! 
 
 Native Americans left the woolen mills before 1880, not forced 
 
 out by recent immigrants. . . . . ,g s 
 
 Americans of native stock coming back to the mills since the 
 
 arrival of the new immigrants 386 
 
 Recent expansion of the woolen industry 387 
 
 Wages stationary prior to the new immigration, increasing since. 
 Wages of unskilled laborers increased at a higher rate than 
 those of skilled operatives . . . . . . 388 
 
 Tales of induced immigration unconfirmed .... 390 
 
 Strike record of English-speaking operatives exceeded by recent 
 
 immigrants .' ^ . . 392 
 
 CHAPTER XX. 
 
 THE IRON AND STEEL WORKERS. 
 
 The "princes of labor" and the "white coolies." . . . 394 
 No "crowding out " of English-speaking workmen by immigrants . 395 
 Highly paid men a small fraction of the force in the past, as in 
 
 the present . . . . . . . . 395 
 
 Wages of unskilled laborers rising . . . . . 397 
 
 Technical revolution in the iron and steel industry . . . 398 
 Retention of skilled men conditioned upon the employment of in- 
 creasing numbers of unskilled laborers .... 400 
 
 New immigrants not working for less pay than natives or older 
 
 immigrants 401 
 
 Wages in the iron and steel industry vary directly as the ratio of 
 
 recent immigrants . .401 
 
 Sunday work and long hours the general rule long before the period 
 of the "new immigration." Demand of employers for an 
 eight-hour day in the 8o's resisted by organized skilled iron v 
 and steel workers. Piece-workers firm for a twelve-hour day . 409 
 The Amalgamated Association a union of skilled workers only. 
 
 Common laborers barred from membership . . . 411 
 
 Decline of the organization due to substitution of machinery for 
 
 skill \ 4 
 
 Attempt of recent immigrants to organize along industrial lines. 413 
 
 CHAPTER XXI. 
 
 THE COAL MINERS. 
 
 The "racial displacement" theory of the Immigration Com- 
 mission ....... 4*4 
 
 Opening of new mining fields the real cause of the westward move- 
 ment of coal miners. . ... 4*6 
 
xviii Contents 
 
 PAGE 
 
 Advancement of experienced miners 421 
 
 Other avenues opened by the general expansion of industry . 422 
 Caste prejudice against the immigrant the outgrowth of occupa- 
 tional stratification 424 
 
 Displacement of the pick-miner by the mining machine: employ- 
 ment of unskilled immigrants the effect, not the cause, of the 
 
 introduction of mining machines 425 
 
 Fluctuations in the demand for coal 432 
 
 Part-time employment in lieu of unemployment . . . 434 
 The migratory worker the product, not the cause, of irregularity 
 
 of employment 435 
 
 Average number of days per man has increased with recent immi- 
 gration 436 
 
 Rise in wages 438 
 
 The company house and the company store as old as the coal- 
 mining industry . 443 
 
 History of the miners' unions in the bituminous coal fields. . 445 
 Biennial conferences between the mine operators and the United 
 
 Mine Workers in the bituminous coal fields . . . 447 
 Competition of unorganized Americans of native stock . . 447 
 Southern and Eastern European immigrants affiliated with miners' 
 
 organizations since the early 8o's; have joined in every strike . 449 
 Violence in strikes not a special characteristic of the recent immi- 
 grants .......... 450 
 
 Failure of the organization in West Virginia and the Southern 
 
 fields not due to immigration 451 
 
 The language question solved in practice 452 
 
 Recognition of the union by the Steel Trust .... 453 
 Miners' unions in the anthracite fields short-lived prior to 1897. 454 
 Capacity of Slavs for compact organization .... 455 
 The strike of 1902: significance of the award of the Anthracite 
 
 Coal Strike Commission 456 
 
 CHAPTER XXII. f 
 
 WORK ACCIDENTS. 
 
 Work accidents attributed to recent immigration. An adaptation 
 
 of the common-law theory of liability for accidents . . 458 
 
 Competition among coal operators the primary cause of waste of 
 
 life in coal mines 462 
 
 Majority of accidents preventable by mining legislation and 
 
 efficient inspection of coal mines ^ 468 
 
 Misleading comparisons between English-speaking and non- 
 English-speaking employees 471 
 
Contents 
 
 XIX 
 
 Decrease of the accident rate in anthracite coal mines . 473 
 Increase of the fatal accident rate in bituminous mines explained 
 
 by their gradual exhaustion .... 4 g o 
 "Negligence" of the miners, psychological effect of mine 
 
 accidents 48o 
 
 Speeding the cause of "carelessness" in the steel mills . . 481 
 
 "Assumption of risk" by the new immigrants .... 482 
 
 Accident rates in coal mines and on railroads compared . . 483 
 Statistics of strikes against dangerous working conditions in the 
 
 United States . . 485 
 
 PART IV. 
 
 CONCLUSION. 
 
 CHAPTER XXIII. 
 
 PROBABLE EFFECTS OF RESTRICTION A FORECAST. 
 
 Plan to improve the condition of labor by checking the develop- 
 ment of industry 487 
 
 Unemployment can not be reduced by restriction of immigration. 488 
 Scarcity of labor not necessarily followed by scarcity wages: 
 
 agricultural labor as an illustration 489 
 
 Labor-saving machinery as a substitute for immigration . . 490 
 
 Farmers and agricultural laborers as a labor reserve . . . 490 
 
 Extension of child labor as a possibility 490 
 
 Further depopulation of rural districts must increase the cost of 
 
 living .......... 491 
 
 Emigration and capital 491 
 
 Effects of a slow expansion of industry 492 
 
 CHAPTER XXIV. 
 
 THE LESSONS OF THE WAR. 
 
 Decline of immigration 493 
 
 "Salutary effects" predicted by the Commission on Industrial 
 
 Relations 493 
 
 Growth of manufactures, mining, and transportation . . 494 
 
 Enormous profits 495 
 
 Shortage of labor .... ..498 
 
 Importation of Mexican peons permitted by the Department of 
 
 Labor . . . . 499 
 
xx Contents 
 
 Mobility of labor 499 
 
 Scholastic theory of wages 500 
 
 Decline of the purchasing power of wages .... 500 
 
 Increase of the proportion of malnourished children . . . 504 
 
 Increase in the number of strikes ...... 505 
 
 Collective bargaining, encouraged by the government . . 505 
 
 Foreign-born workers not responsible for decline in real wages . 506 
 
 Movement of labor from the farms to the factories . . . 506 
 Agricultural production stationary, exports and prices of farm 
 
 products increasing ....... 506 
 
 Migration of Negroes from the South to the North, as a substitute 
 
 for immigration . . . . . . . . 507 
 
 Increased employment of women and children .... 508 
 
 American capital seeking investment in Europe . . .510 
 
 Monopolistic price control 510 
 
 Restriction of immigration no remedy 511 
 
 APPENDIX 
 
 In answer to critics . . , 515 
 
 Note. Importation of Mexican contract-laborers . . . 530 
 
 Statistical Tables . .. . . . . . . . 531 
 
 Alphabetical Index 561 
 
LIST OF TABLES 
 
 TABLE 
 
 1. Per cent who speak English, by years, in the United States. 58 
 
 2. Per cent distribution of immigrants by occupations: 1861- 
 
 1910 67 
 
 3. Ratio of laborers to immigrant breadwinners ... 68 
 
 4. Per cent of illiteracy among the population of Russia, Bul- 
 
 garia, Servia, and Greece, and among the immigrants 
 from the same countries 71 
 
 5. Visits abroad made by foreign-born employees in iron and 
 
 steel mills, by races 75 
 
 6. Per cent of Polish and German employees of packing houses 
 
 in Kansas City, and their foreign-born children six years 
 of age or over, who speak English, by years in the 
 United States . .78 
 
 7. Immigration from Europe compared with increase of popu- 
 
 lation born in Europe . . . . . .88 
 
 8. Movement of third-class passengers between the United 
 
 States and European ports, 1899 to 1909 . . 90 
 
 9. Average monthly immigration and emigration, 1907-1909 . 92 
 10. Immigrants' connections in the United States ... 94 
 n. Assisted immigration ....... 96 
 
 12. Population and immigration 101 
 
 13. Decrease of the population of rural territory, 1900-1910 . 104 
 
 14. Average annual earnings of farm laborers in Kansas, com- 
 
 pared with earnings in similar non-agricultural occupa- 
 tions in the same state, 1900 m- 
 
 15. Distribution of white male laborers, employed in agriculture 
 
 and other pursuits in California, by rates of wages per 
 week (without board), 1906 . . . . . in 
 
 1 6. Range of fluctuations of employment, 1899 and 1904 . . 123 
 
 17. Per cent distribution of native and foreign-born male iron 
 
 and steel workers sixteen years of age and over, by num- 
 ber of months of employment . . . 127 
 
 1 8. Comparative percentages of unemployed and of foreign-born 
 
 breadwinners, by geographical divisions, 1900 . .128 
 
 19. Greatest and least number of male wage-earners employed in 
 
 manufactures during any one month of the year 1899, 
 greatest number of unemployed, and percentage of 
 foreign-born males engaged in manufactures and me- 
 chanical pursuits in 1900, by groups of states . .13 
 
xxii Contents 
 
 TABLE PAGB 
 
 20. Greatest and least number of female wage-earners employed 
 
 in manufactures during any one month of the year 1899, 
 greatest number of unemployed, and percentage of 
 foreign-born females engaged in manufactures and me- 
 chanical pursuits, in 1900, by groups of states . .131 
 
 21. Laborers (male), foreign-born, and unemployed, 1900 . 136 
 
 22. Cotton-mill operatives (male), foreign-born, and unem- 
 
 ployed, 1900 136 
 
 23. Ratio of unemployment in Massachusetts, 1888-1908 . 138 
 
 24. Average number of days worked in bituminous coal mines 
 
 of Pennsylvania, average production per employee per 
 day worked, and number of immigrant miners and 
 laborers destined for Pennsylvania, 1901-1909 . . 140 
 
 25. Average number of wage-earners employed in manufactures, 
 
 1879-1909 . .... 151 
 
 26. Per cent distribution of male breadwinners twenty-one years 
 
 of age and over, by nativity and class of occupations, 1 900 151 
 
 27. Occupations in which the number of native-born decreased, 
 
 1890-1900 152 
 
 28. Decrease from all causes, compared with loss by death among 
 
 native white males of native parentage, in selected oc- 
 cupations, 1890-1900 153 
 
 29. Increase of the number of laborers in the United States, clas- 
 
 sified by race and nativity, 1890-1900 . . .156 
 
 30. Increase of the number of miners in the United States, clas- 
 
 sified by nativity, 1890-1900 . . . . .157 
 
 31. Decrease of the number of native white miners, 1890-1900 . 158 
 
 32. Number of iron and steel workers in the United States, by 
 
 race and nativity, 1880, 1890, and 1900 . . .159 
 
 33. Increase of the number of iron and steel workers in the prin- 
 
 cipal cities of the Middle West, by race and nativity, 
 1890-1900 160 
 
 34. Number and per cent of skilled and unskilled laborers in one 
 
 iron and steel concern, 1907 . . . . .162 
 
 35. Number of English, Welsh, Irish, and German male bread- 
 
 winners, 1890 and 1900 ...... 166 
 
 36. Shifiing of English and Welsh male breadwinners in selected 
 
 occupations, 1890-1900 168 
 
 37. Shifting of Irish male breadwinners in selected occupations, 
 
 1890-1900 169 
 
 38. Shifting of German male breadwinners in selected occupa- 
 
 tions, 1890-1900 . . . . . . .170 
 
 39. Principal nationalities of male breadwinners classified by 
 
 occupation groups (per cent), 1900 . . . .171 
 
Contents xxiii 
 
 TABLE pA 
 
 40. Per cent distribution of foreign-born male breadwinners ac- 
 
 cording to nationality and grade of occupation, 1900 . 172 
 
 41. Increase and decrease of the number of breadwinners in 
 
 Massachusetts classified by sex, nativity, and occupa- 
 tion groups, 1900-1905 I74 
 
 42. Specified occupations in Massachusetts with a decreasing 
 
 number of native breadwinners, classified by sex and 
 nativity, 1900-1905 I75 
 
 43. Foreign-born population of Germany, net emigration and 
 
 net immigration !g o 
 
 44. Migration of workers from Russian Poland to Germany for 
 
 temporary employment, 1890-1904 . . . .181 
 
 45. Comparative growth of railroad mileage and freight traffic in 
 
 Germany and the United States, 1890-1900 . .183 
 
 46. Per cent increase of the population of Germany and of the 
 
 number of breadwinners in trade and manufactures, 
 1882-1907^ 185 
 
 47. Average annual^earnings in Prussian coal mines, 1890-1910 . 186 
 
 48. Membership of trade-unions in Germany, 1890-1900 . .187 
 
 49. Progress of organization among female wage-earners, in Ger- 
 
 many, 1895-1910 188 
 
 50. Comparative summary of the principal expenses of the 
 
 national organizations affiliated with the "General Com- 
 mission of the Trade-Unions of Germany," 1895-1910 . 189 
 
 51. Agricultural progress in Germany, 1895-1909 . . .190 
 
 52. Co-operative associations in Germany, 1903-1908 . . 191 
 
 53. Annual average immigration from Germany, 1875-1910 . 192 
 
 54. Emigration from Germany to all countries outside the 
 
 United States, 1890-1904 194 
 
 55. Scandinavian immigration to the United States, 1881-1910 . 196 
 
 56. Increase of foreign born from the Scandinavian countries and 
 
 from Eastern and Southern Europe, 1880-1910, by geo- 
 graphic divisions .... . 199 
 
 57. Distribution of Scandinavian immigrant breadwinners by 
 
 main classes of occupations, 1881-1910 . . . 201 
 
 58. Immigration from Norway to the United States . . 202 
 
 59. Immigration from Denmark to the United States, 1820-1910 203 
 
 60. Annual average emigration from Sweden by destination, 
 
 1861-1908 .205 
 
 61. Average annual emigration from cities and rural districts of 
 
 Sweden, 1881-1907 206 
 
 62. Annual average emigration from Sweden to other European 
 
 countries, and immigration to Sweden from other Euro- 
 pean countries, 1881-1908 ..... 207 
 
xxiv Contents 
 
 TABLE PAGE 
 
 63. Per cent of wage-earners employed under the system of col- 
 
 lective bargaining in the principal industries of 
 Sweden ........ 209 
 
 64. Number of emigrants from the United Kingdom by destina- 
 
 tion, 1840-1909 212 
 
 65. Net emigration of British subjects from the United Kingdom 
 
 by countries of destination, 1895-1909 . . .210 
 
 66. Average real wages in Great Britain, 1850-1900 . . .215 
 
 67. Annual average emigration from Ireland, May I, 1851, to 
 
 March 31, 1908 ....... 216 
 
 68. Annual average emigration from Ireland by destination, 
 
 1876-1908 . . 217 
 
 69. Families occupying each class of inhabited houses in rural 
 
 areas of Ireland, 1861-1901 ..... 219 
 
 70. Per cent ratio of native white children under five years of 
 
 age, born of native mothers, to native white females, 
 fifteen to forty-four years of age, in cities of less than 
 25,000 inhabitants and rural territory, and per cent ratio 
 of native white male farmers, planters, and overseers, 
 to the total number of white male breadwinners, 1900, 
 by areas comprising states and territories grouped ac- 
 cording to ratio of children, 1900 .... 225 
 
 71. Per cent distribution of the families of Boston according to 
 
 number of families per house, 1855 and 1900 . . 242 
 
 72. Number of tenements of one room occupied by three or more 
 
 persons, 1901 ........ 245 
 
 73. Per cent of families keeping boarders or lodgers among the 
 
 races of the old immigration 252 
 
 74. Per cent of foreign-born families in which wife has employ- 
 
 ment or keeps boarders or lodgers, by yearly earnings 
 
 of husband . . . . . . . . 253 
 
 75. Average annual rent per family and per individual in normal 
 
 families, by nativity, in Northern states . . . 254 
 
 76. Annual rent per family and per individual in normal families, 
 
 by nativity of head of family ..... 255 
 
 77. Average expenditure per man per day of selected families or 
 
 South Italian and native white workers in the iron and 
 steel district of the South . . . .258 
 
 78. Average food expenditures per man per day, by income and 
 
 nationality 260-261 
 
 79. Expenditures for food in normal families with an income 
 
 from $400 to $700, classified by nativity and income . 262 
 
 80. Expenditure for clothing in normal families of unskilled 
 
 laborers, classified by income and nativity . . 267 
 
Contents xxv 
 
 TABLE p ACB 
 
 81. Surplus of income over expenditure of normal families, clas- 
 
 sified by country of birth 268 
 
 82. Per cent of home-owners in the population of Boston, 1845- 
 
 1900 . 377 
 
 83. Percentage of native white home-owners to all occupants, 
 
 classified by parent nativity, in cities with a population 
 
 of 50,000 and over . 278 
 
 84. Percentages of home-owners classified by value of homes, 1 890 278 
 
 85. Home ownership and value of real estate in areas, with ratio 
 
 of home-owners to total families above and below the 
 average, 1890 . . .' 279 
 
 86. Number of houses and apartments advertised for rent to 
 
 white tenants in Washington, D. C., on the last Satur- 
 day in July, 1900 and 1910 282 
 
 87. Average annual deficit per working family in Ohio, by occu- 
 
 pations, 1885 . . . . . . . . 297 
 
 88. Average earnings of factory workers, for a year of 300 working 
 
 days, 1904 . . . . . 298 
 
 89. Average annual earnings of male employees in manufactures, 
 
 collated with the percentages of foreign-born, in the 
 principal states, 1900 300-301 
 
 90. Average annual earnings of female employees in manufactures, 
 
 collated with the percentages of foreign-born, in the prin- 
 cipal states, 1900 . . . . . . . 3 QI 
 
 91. Weekly hours of labor in Massachusetts, 1872 and 1903 . 313 
 
 92. Per cent distribution of factory operatives by weekly hours of 
 
 labor in New York City and in New York state outside 
 
 of New York City, 1901-1910 . . . 3*7 
 
 93. Per cent of children under sixteen employed in factories, in 
 
 the United States and in six leading manufacturing 
 states, and per cent of foreign-born, 1909 . 3'9 
 
 94. Distribution, by parent nativity and color, of the number of 
 
 children of both sexes, ten to fifteen years of age, engaged 
 in manufactures and mechanical pursuits, by geographi- 
 cal divisions, 1900 ..... 3 20 
 
 95. Cotton-mill operatives under fourteen years of age in the 
 
 principal manufacturing states, 1900 
 
 96. Organization of native and immigrant labor . . -327 
 
 97. Organization of immigrant labor ... .328 
 
 98. Number and date of organization of active labor unions in 
 
 six industrial states . . 334 
 
 99. Total wages paid to factory operatives in the United States 
 
 and in the states of New York and Kansas, 1899 and 
 1909 . . . 33 
 
xxvi Contents 
 
 TABLE PACB 
 
 100. Per cent ratio of trade-union membership to urban popula- 
 
 tion in New York and Kansas, 1900-1909 . . . 339 
 
 101. Comparative union membership in the state of New York 
 
 and in the city of New York, 1900 .... 342 
 
 1 02. Comparative union membership in the state of New York 
 
 and in the city of New York, 1900-1910 . . . 343 
 
 103. Number of strikes in Massachusetts, 1830-1905, and Penn- 
 
 sylvania, 1835-1905 344 
 
 104. Strikes and immigration of breadwinners by decennial peri- 
 
 ods, 1861-1905 . .... 345 
 
 105. Agricultural labor unions and strikes among agricultural 
 
 laborers in Italy 350 
 
 1 06. Per cent distribution, by nativity, of lodgers at municipal 
 
 lodging-house in New York City during January, Feb- 
 ruary, and March, 1908, and of the male population 
 twenty-one years of age and over at the XII. Census . 355 
 
 107. Per cent distribution, by nativity, of foreign-born recipients 
 
 of charity, 1854-1860 and 1885-1895, and of the popu- 
 lation of New York City, 1855 and 1890 . . 356 
 
 .108. Comparative percentages of English and Irish paupers in 
 
 Boston, 1837-1845, and in New York City, 1885-1895 356 
 
 109. Per cent distribution of charity cases in New York City, by 
 
 nativity and causes of need 357 
 
 no. Comparative growth of the value of the products of the cloth- 
 ing industry in New York and Baltimore, 1890-1905 . 369 
 
 in. Per cent distribution of foreign-born adult male clothing 
 workers, eighteen years of age and over, residing in the 
 United States less than five years, by race and weekly 
 earnings 370 
 
 112. Per cent of striking employees in the clothing industry and in 
 
 all the United States, 1887-1905 . . . .373 
 
 113. Percentage of immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 
 among the textile mill operatives of Massachusetts, 
 1880-1900 379 
 
 114. Average yearly earnings of cotton-mill operatives, by sex and 
 
 age, in the principal states, 1904 .... 383 
 
 115. Distribution of the operatives of both sexes in the woollen 
 
 and worsted mills of Lawrence, Mass., by parent nativ- 
 ity, 1900 386 
 
 1 16. Number of native Americans of native parentage employed 
 
 in the woolen and worsted mills of Lawrence, 1 900 and 1 909 387 
 
 117. Per cent increase in the rates of wages paid by one of the two 
 
 largest worsted mills in Lawrence to skilled and un- 
 skilled operatives, in 1889-1899 and 1899-1909 . 389 
 
Contents xxvii 
 
 TABLE PAGE 
 
 1 1 8. Classification of employees in selected rolling mills of Ohio, 
 
 by rates of weekly wages, 1884 . . . . 395 
 
 119. Daily wages of employees in steel company No. i, 1880- 
 
 1908 398 
 
 120. Comparative wages of laborers in rolling mills, Ohio, 1884- 
 
 1902 .. 39 8 
 
 121. Employees of Carnegie Steel Company plants in Allegheny 
 
 County, Pa., classified by skill and racial group, March, 
 1907 402 
 
 122. Per cent of skilled iron and steel workers, by location . . 406 
 
 123. Per cent of skilled iron and steel workers, with specified earn- 
 
 ings in Eastern and Southern mills .... 407 
 
 124. Per cent of employees in each department earning twenty-five 
 
 cents and over per hour, in the Pittsburgh and the 
 Southern District ....... 408 
 
 125. Growth of population and of the production of coal, 1880- 
 
 1910 . 419 
 
 126. Number of wage-earners employed in anthracite coal mines, 
 
 and production of coal by five-year periods, 1870-1909 . 437 
 
 127. Union scale of wages in bituminous coal mines, 1898-1908 . 440 
 
 128. Wage scale of employees in the coal mines of one steel com- 
 
 pany in Pennsylvania, 1895-1908 .... 441 
 
 129. Per cent of adult bituminous coal-mine workers of selected 
 
 races earning each specified amount per day, by 
 locality 44 2 
 
 130. Membership of the United Mine Workers of America, 1890- 
 
 1904 .... -447 
 
 131. Number and per cent distribution of fatal accidents in coal 
 
 mines of West Virginia, by principal causes and nativity 
 of persons killed, 1899-1908, and per cent distribution 
 of employees by nativity, 1900 474 
 
 132. Number and per cent of total accidents to coal miners, clas- 
 
 sified by nativity and length of experience in West Vir- 
 ginia, 1899-1908 . . 477 
 
 133. Indices of manufactures, mining, and transportation: 1910, 
 
 1914, 1918 . -495 
 
 134. Net immigration or emigration of breadwinners, 1915* 
 
 I 9 I9 .... ; 498 
 
 135. Purchasing power of union wage rates, measured by retail 
 
 prices of food, 1913-1918 . S^ 1 
 
 136. Proportion of malnourished school children in the Borough 
 
 of Manhattan, New York City 5<>4 
 
 137. Wheat produced, exported, and retained for consumption, 
 
 1911-1918 . , , . i , 5 06 
 
xxviii Contents 
 
 TABLE PACK 
 
 138. Index numbers of the yearly production, and prices of veg- 
 etable products, 1913-1918 . 507 
 
 APPENDIX 
 
 I. Annual average immigration distributed by occupa- 
 tions, 1861-1910 531 
 
 II. Fluctuations of employment of male wage-earners in 
 
 the month of May, 1899 . . 53 1 
 
 III. Maximum and minimum numbers of wage-earners em- 
 
 ployed in manufactures during any one month, 
 number and per cent unemployed, 1899, and per 
 cent foreign-born engaged in manufacturing and 
 mechanical pursuits, 1900^ by sex and by states, 533 
 
 IV. Percentage ratios of unemployed and of foreign white 
 
 breadwinners in the principal occupations, 1900, 536 
 V. Bituminous coal mines: greatest and least numbers 
 employed, per cent unemployed at any time during 
 the year 1902, and per cent foreign white miners in 
 1900, in the principal states .... 538 
 VI. Laborers, male: per cent foreign white, and per cent 
 
 unemployed, by states, 1900 . . . -539 
 VII. Cotton-mill operatives, male: per cent foreign white 
 
 and per cent unemployed, by states, 1900 . . 540 
 VIII. Persons employed in all industries of Massachusetts, 
 
 1888-1908 541 
 
 IX. Immigrant breadwinners destined for Massachusetts, 
 
 1897-1908 . . . . . . . 541 
 
 X. Increase or decrease of the number of breadwinners, 
 classified by sex, nativity, and occupation, in the 
 United States, 1890-1900 . . . 542 
 
 XI. Number and increase or decrease, of foreign-born white 
 male breadwinners, classified by nationality and 
 occupation, 1890-1900 . . Facing 544 
 
 XII. Foreign-born engaged in gainful occupations in Ger- 
 many, 1900 . -545 
 
 XIII. Foreign born in Germany, by country of birth, 1880- 
 
 1900 545 
 
 XIV. Foreign-born population from the Scandinavian coun- 
 
 tries and from Southern and Eastern Europe, by 
 states, 1880, 1890, 1900, and 1910 . . . 546 
 XV. Emigration from the United Kingdom, by destination 
 
 of emigrants, 1840-1909 . . . . . 546 
 
Contents xxix 
 
 TABLH 
 
 XVI. Congestion in Dublin: classification of tenements of 
 four rooms or less, by number of rooms and by num- 
 ber of persons per tenement, 1901 . . .548 
 XVII. Representative household expenditures for food in the 
 iron district of the South, for the period of one week 
 in 1909 ........ 549 
 
 XVIII. Earnings and expenses in Massachusetts, 1800, 1830, 
 
 and 1860 ....... 549 
 
 XIX. Average income and expenditures of wage-earners in 
 
 specified occupations, in New Jersey, 1885 . 550 
 XX. Average income and expenditures of unskilled laborers 
 in New Jersey, classified by nativity and source of 
 income, 1885 ....... 550 
 
 XXI. Average wages and average expenses of working families 
 
 with deficits, in Ohio, 1885 55 1 
 
 XXII. Organized workers and male white breadwinners, en- 
 gaged in non-agricultural pursuits, in Illinois and 
 New Jersey, classified by nativity . . . 552 
 
 XXIII. Male labor-union membership and immigration, New 
 
 York state, 1897-1910 ..... 552 
 
 XXIV. Urban population, membership of labor unions and per- 
 
 centage of organized industrial wage-earners in 
 New York and Kansas, 1900-1909 . . -553 
 XXV. Daily wages in steel company No. i, 1880-1908 . . 553 
 XXVI. Per cent of machine-mined bituminous coal, and per 
 cent ratio of foreign born from Southern and East- 
 ern Europe for each of the principal coal-producing 
 states, 1900 and 1910 . ... 555 
 
 XXVII. Per cent of miners of Southern and Eastern European 
 parentage, lives lost per million tons, and per 1,000 
 employees, in bituminous coal mines . . . 555 
 XXVIII. Number of employees, and fatal accident rates in the 
 
 anthracite mines of Pennsylvania, 1870-1909 . 556 
 XXIX. Number of fatal accidents, and ratio per 1,000 em- 
 
 ployees on railroads and in coal mines, 1889-1908 . 557 
 XXX. Arrival and departure of aliens, 1908-1920 . . 558 
 XXXI. Immigration and emigration of breadwinners, 1915- 
 
 1919 ..... 559 
 
 XXXII. Comparison of persons seeking work and workers called 
 for by employers at public employment offices in 
 the state of New York, 1916-1918 . . 559 
 
 XXXIII. Exports or principal breadstuffs, other than wheat, from 
 
 the United States, 1910-1918 . . .560 
 
LIST OF DIAGRAMS 
 
 DIAGRAM PAGB 
 
 I. Immigration and business conditions, 1880-1910 . 87 
 II. Movement of third-class passengers between the United 
 
 States and European ports, 1899-1909 . 89 
 
 III. Monthly immigration and emigration, from July, 1907, 
 
 to May, 1909 . ... -91 
 
 IV. Relative per capita production of coal, agricultural 
 
 staples and live stock I0 5 
 
 V. Average number of male wage-earners employed in 
 manufactures in the United States and in principal 
 
 states, by months, 1899 118 
 
 VI. Per cent unemployed 122 
 
 VII. Per cent unemployed at any time during the year, and 
 per cent of foreign born in fifty leading occupations, 
 
 1900 . 133 
 
 VIII. Ratio of unemployment in bituminous coal mines, 1902, 
 
 and percentage of foreign-born miners, 1900 . 134 
 IX. Ratio of unemployment of factory workert m Massachu- 
 setts, and number of immigrant breadwinners des- 
 tined for Massachusetts, 1897-1908 . . -139 
 X. Average number of days worked in the bituminous coal 
 mines of Pennsylvania, and number of immigrant 
 miners and laborers destined for Pennsylvania, 
 
 1901-1909 141 
 
 XI. Days of employment in organized trades in the state 
 of New York, and number of immigrant breadwin- 
 - ners destined for New York, 1897-1909 . .144 
 XII. Per cent of increase of the production of coal in the 
 United States, Germany, and Great Britain, 1890- 
 1909 .184 
 
 XIII. Production of pig iron in Germany, the United States, 
 
 and the United Kingdom, 1880-1910 . . 184 
 
 XIV. Emigration from Germany to all countries outside of 
 
 the United States, and per cent of Southern and 
 Eastern European immigration to the total immi- 
 gration to the United States, 1890-1904 . . 195 
 XV. Increase of Scandinavians and of Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans in a group of eleven western states and 
 in the remainder of the United States, 1 880- 1 9 1 o . 197 
 
Contents 
 
 DIAGRAM PACK 
 
 XVI. Net emigration from the United Kingdom, by destina- 
 tion, 1895-1909 214 
 
 XVII. Per cent ratio of home owners and tenants to all families, 
 classified by age periods and by geographical divi- 
 sions, 1890 280-281 
 
 XVIII. Average daily wages of railroad employees, 1891-1909 . 304 
 XIX. Medians of relative cost of living and average of bien- 
 nial medians of relative wages, 1861-1865 . . 308 
 XX. Labor-union membership in the state of New York, 
 number of immigrant breadwinners destined for 
 the state of New York, and combined imports and 
 exports through the port of New York, 1897-1910 336 
 XXI. Male union membership in the states of New York and 
 Kansas, 1900-1909, per cent ratio to the number 
 of industrial wage-earners in 1900 . . . 340 
 XXII. Number of persons employed in bituminous coal mines, 
 
 1880, 1889, and 1907 ..... 420 
 
 XXIII. Per cent of bituminous coal mined by machine, 1900 
 
 and 1910, compared with per cent ratio of Southern 
 and Eastern European miners to all miners, 1900; 
 and with per cent ratio of Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans to the total population, 1910, for the 
 principal states ...... 429 
 
 XXIV. Coal production by months, in Illinois, 1906-1910 . 433 
 XXV. Fatal accident rates in coal mines per 1,000 workmen 
 
 employed in the United States and foreign coun- 
 tries 469 
 
 XXVI. Fatal accident rates in coal mines, 1889-1908, and per- 
 centage of miners of 'Slavic and Italian parentage 
 in 1900, in the principal states . . . 472 
 XXVII. Fatal accident rates in anthracite coal mines, 1870-1909 479 
 XXVIII. Fatal accident rates per 1,000 employees on railroads 
 
 and in coal mines, 1889-1908 .... 485 
 
 XXIX. Indices of physical production for agriculture, mining, 
 
 and manufacture, 1899-1919 .... 496 
 
 MAPS 
 
 Per cent ratio of native white children under five years of age, born 
 of native mothers, to native white females fifteen to forty- 
 four years of age in cities of less than 25,000 inhabitants and 
 rural territory, 1900 . . . Facing 227 
 
 Production of coal in states with an annual output of not less than 
 
 1,000,000 tons 416-417 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 PART I 
 
 SUMMARY REVIEW 
 
 IT is the purpose of this review to state briefly for the 
 benefit of the busy reader the results of our inquiry into 
 the various phases of the immigration question. Such a 
 summary must necessarily be dogmatic in form. Every 
 proposition is advanced here, however, merely as a theorem, 
 whose demonstration is presented in its proper place, in 
 another part of the book. 
 
 It is recognized on all sides that the present movement for 
 restriction of immigration has a purely economic object: the 
 restriction of competition in the labor market. Organized 
 labor demands the extension of the protectionist policy to 
 the home market in which "hands" the laborer 's only 
 commodity are offered for sale. The advocates of restric- 
 tion believe that every immigrant admitted to this country 
 takes the place of some American workingman. At the 
 inception of the restrictionist movement, in the 8o's and the 
 early 90*8, they were avowedly opposed to immigration in 
 general. The subsequent decline of immigration from the 
 British Isles, Germany, and the Scandinavian countries 
 and the increase of immigration from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe have diverted the attack from immigration in general 
 to "the new immigration" from Southern and Eastern 
 
 2 
 
2 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Europe an4 the Asiatic provinces of Turkey. Yet while the 
 root of 'allevil is now sought in the racial makeup of the new 
 imniigratioi?; as contrasted- with the old, every objection to 
 the immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe is but 
 an echo of the complaints which were made at an earlier day 
 against the then new immigration from Ireland, Germany, 
 and even from England. Three quarters of a century 
 ago, as to-day, the only good immigrants were the dead 
 immigrants. 
 
 There is no real ground for the popular opinion that the 
 immigrants of the present generation are drawn from a 
 poorer class than their predecessors. It is a historical fact 
 that prior to 1820 the great majority of the immigrants were 
 too poor to prepay their passage, which never cost as much 
 as $50 per steerage passenger; the usual way for a poor man 
 to secure transportation for himself and family was to con- 
 tract to be sold into servitude after arrival. The next gene- 
 ration of immigrants was not much better off. According to 
 contemporary testimony, the millions of Irish and Germans 
 who came in the middle of the nineteenth century were 
 ignorant and accustomed to a very low standard of living. 
 Since the races of Southern and Eastern Europe have 
 become predominant among immigrants to the United 
 States, the steerage rates have been doubled, the increase 
 being equivalent to a heavy head tax. The higher cost of 
 transportation must have raised the financial standard 
 of the new immigration, as compared with the immigrant? 
 of the 70*5 and the early 8o's. This inference is borne out 
 by the fact that the percentage of illiteracy is much lower 
 among the immigrants than among their countrymen who 
 remain at home. Illiteracy is generally the effect of pov- 
 erty. The higher literacy of the immigrant may be accep- 
 ted as evidence that economically the immigrant must be 
 above the average of his mother country. 
 
 The complaint that the new immigrants do not easily 
 "assimilate" is also as old as immigration itself. To-day 
 the Germans are reckoned by courtesy among the " English- 
 
"Summary Review 3 
 
 speaking races." But as late as the middle of the nineteenth 
 century the growth of German colonies in all large cities 
 caused the same apprehension in the minds of their Ameri- 
 can contemporaries as the Jewish, the Italian, and the Slav 
 colonies of our day. Statistics show, however, that the new 
 immigrant races number among them as large a percentage 
 of English-speaking persons as the Germans who have lived 
 in the United States the same length of time. 
 
 The only real difference between the old immigration and 
 the new is that of numbers. To the workman wKo com- 
 plains that he has been crowded out of his job by another, 
 it would afford little comfort to feel that the man who had 
 taken his place was of Teuton or Celtic, rather than of 
 Latin or Slav stock. The true reason why the "old immi- 
 gration " is preferred is that there is very much less of it. 
 
 As stated, the demand for restriction proceeds from the 
 assumption that the American labor market is overstocked ; 
 by immigration. Comparative statistics of industry and 
 population in the United States show, however,' that immi- 
 gration merely follows opportunities for employment. In 
 times of business expansion immigrants enter in increasing 
 numbers; in times of business dcglfcjsion their numbers 
 decline. The immigration movemW^.is further balanced 
 by emigration from the United States. As a rule, the causes 
 which retard immigration also accelerate the return move- 
 ment from this country. It is customary to condemn the 
 "bird of passage," but so long as there are variations in 
 business activity from season to season and from year to 
 year, the American wage-earner has no cause to complain of 
 the immigrants who choose to leave this country tempo- 
 rarily while there is no demand for their services, thereby 
 reducing unemployment in its acutest stage. 
 
 It is broadly asserted by restriction advocates that the 
 hundreds of thousands of Slav, Italian, Greek, Syrian, and 
 other immigrant mine and mill workers have been "im- 
 ported" by capitalists- in other words, that they are all con- 
 tract laborers. This belief offers to the student of folk-lore 
 
4 Immigration and Labor 
 
 a typical example of twentieth century myth-building. None 
 of the official investigations of immigration has disclosed 
 any evidence of importation of laborers under contract 
 on a large scale, although prior to the enactment of 
 the law of 1885 excluding contract laborers there was no 
 reason to conceal the fact. It is quite conceivable that in 
 the case of a strike a great corporation might have resorted 
 to the importation of a large force of strikebreakers re- 
 gardless of cost. As a general rule, however, with hundreds 
 of thousands of immigrants coming to this country an- 
 nually, it would be a waste of money to "induce" immi- 
 gration. The few actual violations of the contract labor 
 law that elude the vigilance of the immigration authorities 
 cannot affect the labor market. 
 
 The real agents who regulate the immigration movement 
 are the millions of earlier immigrants already in the United 
 States. It is they that advance the cost of passage of a^ 
 large proportion of the new immigrants. When the outlook 
 for employment is good, they send for their relatives, or 
 encourage their friends to come. When the demand for 
 labor is slack, the foreign-born workman must hold his 
 savings in reserve, JJorovide for possible loss of employ- 
 ment. At such tim(Jpo wage-earner will assume the bur- 
 den of providing for a relative or friend, who might for a long 
 time be unable to secure employment. It is in this way 
 that the business situation in the United States reacts upon 
 the volume of immigration. The fluctuating supply of 
 immigrant labor, like that of any other commodity, may 
 sometimes outrun the demand and at other times lag behind 
 it, yet, if we compare the totals for industrial cycles, com- 
 prising years of panic, of depression, and of prosperity, 
 within the past sixty years, we find that the ratio of immi- 
 gration to population has been well-nigh constant. In the 
 long run immigration adjusts itself to the demand for labor. 
 
 This proposition seems to be inconsistent with the pres- 
 ence at all times of a vast number of unemployed. Ap- 
 parently, there are already more men than jobs in the 
 
Summary Review 
 
 United States; every new immigrant, in order to live, must 
 take away the job from some one else who has been here 
 before. On closer study, however, it is found that unem- "jgT: 
 ployment is not the effect of an absolute surplus population. .' 
 It arises, notwithstanding a growing demand for labor, from 
 the fluctuations in the distribution of the demand. The 
 most generally recognized cause of unemployment is sea- 
 sonal variation of business activity. There are trades 
 dependent largely upon climatic conditions and partly upon 
 social customs. In the period of maximum activity the 
 demand for labor in such trades may often so far exceed the 
 supply as to necessitate overtime work; yet this shortage of 
 labor will not save a portion of the force from idleness at 
 other times of the year. The only class of labor which is L/ 
 capable of shifting from one industry to another in response 
 to variations in demand is unskilled labor. But the locali- 
 zation of industries sets a limit to the mobility of unskilled 
 labor. In order to eliminate unemployment it would be 
 necessary to dovetail the busy and the slack seasons in the 
 various industries upon such a plan as would produce an 
 even distribution of the work of thej^^n over all seasons 
 of the year. This might be possij^ ^tonines, mills, and 
 transportation lines were operatedB Ration- wide trust. 
 So long, however, as production iSHPned by many com- 
 peting employers, each subject to his own vicissitudes of 
 business, insecurity of employment is inevitable. The 
 normal state of every industry is o have a larger force 
 than can ever find employment in it at any one time. The 
 labor reserve is as much a part of the industrial system as 
 the regular force. / 
 
 Still, the labor market being normally overstocked, it 
 sounds plausible that the immigrant, who is accustomed to 
 a lower standard of living at home than the American work- 
 man, will be able to underbid and displace his American 
 competitor. : 'lf this view were correct, we should find, in 
 the first place, a higher percentage of unemployment among j 
 *v, - than among the foreign-born breadwinners. 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 Statistics, however, show that the proportion of unemploy- 
 ment is the same for native and foreign-born wage-earners. 
 The immigrant has no advantage over the native American 
 in securing or retaining employment. In the next place, 
 , we should find more unemployment in those sections of the 
 United States where the immigrants are most numerous. 
 In fact, however, the ratio of unemployment in manufac- 
 tures is the same in the North Atlantic States with a large 
 immigrant population as in the South Atlantic States where 
 the percentage of foreign-born is negligible. Coal miners are 
 thought to have suffered most from immigration. Yet it ap- 
 pears that Pennsylvania, which is among the States with the 
 highest percentages of foreign-born miners, has the second 
 lowest percentage of unemployment. The highest ratio of 
 unemployment , according to the latest published census data, 
 was found in West Virginia, where the percentage of foreign- 
 born miners was next to the lowest. A similar relation 
 between unemployment and the proportion of immigrants is 
 observed among cotton-mill operatives and common labor- 
 ers: immigrants are not attracted to those States where 
 opportunities for j^ular employment are less favorable. 
 
 Furthermore, ijfl Hoisted a causal connection between 
 immigration anr: i fcyment, there should have been 
 more unemployrnMMMRose years when immigration was 
 greater, and vice versa. The figures show, on the contrary, 
 that there was less unemployment during the first seven 
 years of the present century with immigration at a high 
 tide than during the preceding decade when immigration 
 was at a low ebb. 
 
 Still an oversupply of labor may produce a latent form of 
 unemployment which could be described as underemploy- 
 ment: all employees may be kept on the rolls, and yet be 
 idle a part of every week. Again, however, we find that the 
 average number of days of employment per wage-earner 
 increases as immigration increases^-and declines as immi- 
 gration declines. 
 
Summary Review 7 
 
 The relation between immigration and unemployment 
 may thus be su> -JV^J 1 ^J 16 following propositions: 
 
 Unemployment and immigf ati6tf are the effects of economic 
 \forces working in opposite directions: those^ which produce 
 business expansion reduce unemployment and attract immi- 
 gration; those which produce business depression increase 
 unemployment and reduce immigration. 
 
 Yet it may be said that while immigration is not a con- 
 tributory cause of unemployment, restriction of immigra- 
 tion might nevertheless reduce unemployment. This sup- 
 position is negatived by the experience of Australia, where 
 emigration exceeds immigration. Australia is a new coun- 
 try with an area as great as that of the United States, while 
 its population at the census of 1906 was half a million short 
 of the population of New York City at the census of 1910. / 
 Yet Australia has as much unemployment as the State of 
 New York, which is teeming with immigrants. It is evident 
 that unemployment is produced by the modern organiza- 
 tion of industry even in the absence of immigration. 
 
 There is a widespread belief that, although on the whole 
 the United States is in need of immigrant labor, "the new 
 immigration" has a tendency to stagnate in the overpopu- 
 lated cities, while there is a keen demand for hands in agri- 
 cultural sections. A retrospective view of the history of 
 Immigration shows that this tendency is not peculiar to 
 "the new immigration." For the past ninety years public 
 men ancf social theorists have sought to relieve unemploy- 
 ment in the cities by directing the current of immigration 
 to the farm, but the immigrants have always preferred to 
 seek employment in the cities. The popular mind Which 
 accounts for individual conduct by the "free will" of the 
 individual applies the same criterion to social phenomena: 
 the Italians and the Slavs concentrate in the cjties because 
 they have a "racial tendency" to concentrate^ the cities. 
 That most of the immigrants of those nationalities have 
 grownup in agricultural communities a'nd that many of them 
 after working a few years in a great American city return 
 
8 Immigration and Labor 
 
 home and go back to the soil, argues against the assumption 
 "lota "racial" dislike for agriculture. The real cause of the 
 
 Concentration of immigrants in the cities is economic. Even 
 the "desirable" immigrant from Northern and Western 
 
 . Europe who lands with a capital of fifty and odd dollars 
 
 ** lacks the funds to rent a farm. At best he can obtain em- 
 ployment only as a farm hand. Since the early days of Irish 
 
 V and German immigration, however, the growing industries 
 of the cities have offered a better market for labor than 
 agriculture. 
 
 The industrial development of the United States has 
 manifested itself in a relative, and in some sections an 
 absolute, depopulation of rural territory. There is a large 
 migration of native Americans of native stock from country 
 to city. This movement is the result of the revolution 
 
 , in American farming conditions and methods, which has 
 
 * tended to reduce the demand for labor on the farm. The 
 American farm of the first half of the nineteenth century was 
 .the seat of a highly diversified industry. The members of a 
 farm household made their own tools and part of the furni- 
 ture; they were spinners and weavers; they made their own 
 Clothes, and soap and candles for their own use. WitlTsuch 
 a variety of occupations there was work for a hired man at 
 all seasons of the year. But industrial differentiation has 
 removed from the farm one industry after another. The 
 time during which a hired man can be kept employed on the 
 farm has been reduced in consequence to a few months in 
 the year. Still until the middle of the nineteenth century the 
 mills were quite commonly run by water power, which 
 made for decentralization of manufactures. The small 
 country towns accordingly offered to the farm laborer a 
 prospect of employment when work was scarce on the farm. 
 But the general substitution of steam for water power led to 
 the removal of factories from small towns to great commer- 
 
 /xaal centers. The opportunity to. earn a full year's wages 
 ( in a rural community was gone. 
 
 While in manufacturing 'the invention of labor-saving 
 
Summary Review 9 
 
 machinery has resulted in the gradual displacement of the 
 small proprietor by the wage-earner, in American agriculture, 
 on the contrary, the machine has tended to eliminate the 
 wage-earner. As late as the middle of the nineteenth century 
 the agricultural methods of the American farmer differed 
 little from those of his ancestors. Grass was mowed with a 
 scythe. Grain was cut with a sickle and threshed with a 
 flail. Flailing and winnowing grain was the chief farm 
 work of the winter. Corn was planted by hand, cultivated 
 with the hoe, and shelled by scraping the ears against the 
 handle of a frying pan. The cultivation of a farm in this 
 primitive way sustained a demand for steady farm help in 
 all seasons. To-day there is some implement or machine 
 for every kind of farm work. It is estimated that the quan- 
 tity of labor saved by machinery represents the services 
 of one and a half million men working every week day in 
 the year. 
 
 In consequence of limited demand', agricultural labor is 
 the least remunerative of all occupations. The hours of 
 labor* on the farm are longer than even in the steel mills of 
 Pennsylvania. Small pay, long hours, and irregular 
 employment is what the immigrant can expect on a farm. 
 His preference for city work which pays better can be easily 
 explained without delving into the mysteries of race psy- 
 chology. It merely confirms the rule that immigration 
 follows the demand for labor. 
 
 The effect of immigration upon labor in the United States ^_ 
 has been, a readjustment of the population on the scalejof ^ 
 occupations. The majority of Americans of native paren- 
 tage are engaged in farrning, in business, in trie? professions, 
 
 and in clerical pursuits, f The majority of the immigrants, ^ 
 
 on the other hand, are industrial wage-earners. Only in 
 exceptional cases has this readjustment been attended by 
 actual displacement of the native or Americanized wage- 
 earner. In the course o^trial evolution some fr^es 
 have declined owing to thr !i :; reduction of new methods ot 
 production. In such cases there was naturally a decrease of 
 
io Immigration and Labor 
 
 the number of native as well as of foreign-born workers. 
 As a rule, however, the supply of immigrant labor has been 
 absorbed by the increasing demand for labor in all industries 
 without leaving a surplus sufficient to displace the native or 
 older immigrant wage-earner. There were but a few occu- 
 pations which showed an actual, not a relative decrease of 
 native Americans of native stock. This decrease was due 
 to the disinclination of the young generation to follow the 
 pursuits of their fathers; the new accessions from native 
 stock were insufficient to replace the older men as they were 
 dying off, and the vacancies were gradually filled up by 
 immigrants. But for every position given up by a native 
 American there were many new openings filled by native 
 American wage-earners. 
 
 The westward movement of American and Americanized 
 wage-earners and the concentration of immigrants in a few 
 Eastern and Central States have been interpreted as the 
 "displacement" of the English-speaking workmen from the 
 mills and mines of the East by the new immigration. An 
 examination of the figures shows, however, that durinf the 
 past thirty years mining and manufacturing grew much 
 faster in the West and South than in the East and drew some 
 of the native workers and earlier immigrants from the older 
 manufacturing. States. But the demand for labor grew in 
 the old States as well. The places left vacant by the old 
 employees who had gone westward had to be filled by new 
 immigrants. 
 
 The desertion of mills and factories by native American 
 girls has also been explained as their "displacement" by 
 immigrants. The motive assigned is not economic, but 
 racial : it is the social prejudice against the immigrant that 
 has forced the American girl to quit. It seems, however, 
 that this explanation mistakes cause for effect: the social 
 stigma attaching to working association with immigrants is 
 not the cause but the effect of the desertion of the mills and 
 factories by native American women. The psychological 
 interpretation overlooks one of the greatest economic 
 
Summary Review n 
 
 changes that has taken place in the United States since the 
 Civil War: the admission of women to most of the pursuits 
 which were formerly regarded as peculiarly masculine. For 
 every native woman of American parentage who left the 
 mill or clothing factory there were forty women of the same 
 nativity who found new openings. The increase of the 
 number of native American professional women was nearly 
 five times as great as the decrease of the number of native 
 American factory girls. The marvelous progress of the, 
 American educational system has fitted the native American^ 
 woman for other work than manual labor and has at the 
 same time opened to her a new field in which she does not 
 meet the competition of the immigrant. 
 
 There is absolutely no statistical proof of an oversupply 
 of unskilled labor resulting in the displacement of native * 
 by immigrant laborers. No decrease of the number of 
 common laborers among the native white of native or for- 
 eign parentage appears in any of the great States which 
 serve as receptacles for immigration. The same is true of 
 miners. In none of the States affected by the new immi- 
 gration has there been a decrease in the number of native 
 miners. Such States as Pennsylvania and Illinois showed 
 large increases in the number of native miners, both of for- 
 eign and native parentage. The iron and steel mills are 
 another industry from which the recent immigrants are 
 popularly believed to have forced out the native workmen 
 and older English-speaking immigrants.. The fact is, that 
 in the earlier period of the industry, when immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe was negligible, the number 
 of American employees increased very slowly; during the 
 recent period, on the contrary, since the immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe have been coming in large 
 numbers, the number of American-born employees of every 
 nativity has more than doubled. The increased employment 
 of native Americans is recorded in the figures for every im- 
 portant iron- and steel-producing State, as well as for every 
 city holding a leading place in the iron and steel industry. 
 
12 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The effect of immigration upon the occupational distribu- 
 tion of the industrial wage-earners has been the elevation of 
 
 the English-speaking workmen to the status of an aris- 
 tocracy of labor, while the immigrants have been employed 
 to perform the rough work of all industries. Though the in- 
 troduction of machinery has had the tendency to reduce the 
 relative number of skilled mechanics, yet the rapid pace of 
 industrial expansion has increased the number of skilled and 
 supervisory positions so fast that practically all the English- 
 ^ speaking employees have had the opportunity to rise on the 
 scale of occupations. This opportunity, however, was con- 
 ditioned upon a corresponding increase of the totM opera- 
 ting force. It is only because the new immigration has 
 ! furnished the class of unskilled laborers that the native 
 
 "~ workmen and older immigrants have been raisedVt <Afche 
 ^ plane of an aristocracy of labor. $ y 
 
 Yet, while the number of native American workmen in ajl 
 industries has increased, it is true that in some occupation^ 
 there has been an actual decrease of the number of English, 
 Welsh, Irish, and German workers, which has been con- 
 strued as ' ' displacement ' ' of Americanized workers by immi- 
 . grants from Southern and Eastern Europe with a lower 
 standard of living. This interpretation overlooks the fact 
 that native workers of native parentage, presumably with as 
 high a standard of living as the Irish, are found in the same 
 occupations in larger numbers than formerly. Another v 
 fact that contradicts the popular view is the increase of the 
 number of Scotch immigrants in those ver} r occupations 
 which show a decline in the number of English and Irish. 
 Judged by any standard, the Scotch are not inferior to other 
 immigrants from the United Kingdom. The increased 
 employment of the Scotch in the principal occupations, 
 including even common laborers, warrants the conclusion 
 that the decline in the numbers of English and Irish must 
 have been due to other causes than ;the competition of recent 
 immigrants with lower standards c Hiving. A further fact 
 that must be considered in thit, connection is that the 
 
Summary Review 13 
 
 English, Welsh, and Irish farmers exhibit a greater decrease, 
 both absolute and relative, than any other occupational 
 group among the same nationalities. Evidently no new 
 farmers came to fill the places of their countrymen who 
 were carried off by death, although the aliens from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe kept away from the fanning sections 
 and left the field open for English, Welsh, and Irish 
 immigrants. / 
 
 The real explanation of the decrease in the number of 
 immigrants from Northern and Western Europe in the occu- 
 pations which rank lowest in the social scale is that the 
 earlier immigrants have worked their way upward. Among 
 the breadwinners born in Northern and Western Europe, 
 farmers, business men, professional men, and skilled mechan- 
 ics outnumber those who are employed in the coarser grades 
 of labor. The latter have been left to immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. ^ 
 
 There has been a great deal of speculation to the effect 
 that had immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 been kept out of the United States, the immigrants from 
 'Northern and Western Europe would, as of old, have sup- 
 plied the demand of American industry for unskilled labor. 
 The fallacy of this assumption is apparent from a consid- 
 eration of the comparative growth of population in the 
 United States and in the countries of Northern and Western 
 Europe, as well as of the economic conditions in those coun- 
 tries. As stated before, immigration in the long run bears ! 
 a constant relation to the population of the United States. 
 Inasmuch, however, as the latter increases faster than the 
 population of Europe, especially that of the emigration 
 countries, the rate of emigration from those countries must 
 increase much faster than their population in order to sup- 
 ply the American industries with the number of immigrants 
 they can employ. Yet the volume of emigration from any 
 country can not increase beyond a certain limit set by the. 
 size of its population. When that point is reached, further 
 industri--" o in the United States must draw upon 
 
14 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the labor supply of other countries. In order to replace the 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe that were 
 absorbed by the industrial expansion of the past decade, 
 immigration from Great Britain, Germany, and the Scan- 
 dinavian countries should have risen to the Irish level, 
 whereas Ireland ought to have been depopulated at a 
 greater rate than in the years of the Irish famine. The 
 recent development of those countries, however, has had a 
 decided tendency to check emigration. 
 
 In the closing years of the nineteenth century Germany 
 ceased to be a country of emigration, and became a country 
 of immigration. Inasmuch as Germany draws her immigrant 
 supply from the same sources as the United States, it is 
 evident that the German wage-earner does not stay away 
 from the United States in order to escape the competition 
 of the immigrant from Southern and Eastern Europe. The 
 transformation of Germany from an emigrant-furnishing 
 nation to a country of immigration is the direct result of her 
 recent economic development. Until the middle of the 
 nineteenth century Germany was principally an agricultural 
 country. About that time German agriculture reached the 
 point where the growth of land values made the tradi- 
 tional methods of the peasant unprofitable and necessi- 
 tated a transition to intensive systems of cultivation. 
 Many a peasant who lacked the requisite capital for a 
 .change of methods was forced to dispose of his land and to 
 seek a new home in the United States. In Prussian Poland 
 this crisis came in the 70*5 and the early 8o's and drove large 
 numbers of Polish peasants to the United States. But the 
 rapid growth of manufacturing and mining during the last 
 twenty-five years has absorbed the whole natural increase of 
 the rural population. At the same time, German agricul- 
 ture has also made substantial progress. As a result, there 
 is a scarcity of agricultural laborers during the busy season. 
 The combined effect of all these causes, coupled with the 
 disappearance of cheap lands ir X1 " TT -* A ~ J o^^ % 
 reflected in a decline of the em ration g 
 
Summary Review 15 
 
 laborers to the United States. The increased demand for 
 labor has resulted in a substantial increase of the rates of 
 wages, simultaneously with a marked reduction of the work- 
 ing day. These gains are in no small way due to the pro- 
 gress of organization among German wage-earners, which 
 was practically prohibited prior to 1891. Since that time 
 the membership of labor organizations has advanced by 
 leaps and bounds, leaving behind the older British and 
 American trade-unions. The growth of the labor move- 
 ment in Germany has directly and indirectly stimulated 
 labor legislation, which has conferred material benefits upon 
 the German wage-earner. Whereas industrial progress in 
 modern times has generally led to the elimination of the 
 independent artisan who has been pushed into the ranks of 
 wage-earners, in Germany this process has been checked by 
 the development of co-operation. The general improve- 
 ment of the economic conditions of all classes of the working 
 people necessarily affected the rate of emigration for the past 
 twenty years. 
 
 Yet it is worthy of note that whije immigration from 
 Germany to the United States has in recent years been much 
 below the level of the early 8o's, the average annual immi- 
 gration from Germany was much higher during the past 
 decade than during the last decade of the nineteenth 
 century. In other words, German immigration increased 
 with the increase of Italian and Slav immigration to the 
 United States. 
 
 Coming next to Scandinavian immigration we find that the 
 number of breadwinners coming to compete in the American 
 labor market virtually reached its maximum during the 
 past decade. The only change is that, whereas the earlier 
 Scandinavian immigration was mostly of a family type, 
 among the recent Scandinavian immigrants single persons 
 vastly predominate. This change is due to the fact that 
 the old Scandinavian immigrants came largely to settle on 
 wher^k family was a help, while the new Scandina- 
 ntSglike the new immigration from Southern 
 
 .*.' 
 
16 Immigration and Labor 
 
 and Eastern Europe, come chiefly to seek industrial employ- 
 ment. That Scandinavian immigration to the United 
 States was in no way affected by immigration from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe is evidenced by the change in 
 the direction of the former: whereas prior to 1890 the 
 greater part of Scandinavian immigration was directed to 
 the agricultural States of the Central West and Northwest, 
 since 1890 the majority of the Scandinavian immigrants 
 follow the current of immigration from Southern and East- 
 ern Europe. The bulk of the Scandinavian immigrants 
 are laborers from agricultural districts or farm workers 
 without special mechanical skill. It is these unskilled 
 Scandinavian laborers that have in recent years sought 
 employment in competition with unskilled Slav and Italian 
 laborers. The reason why the number of these Scandi- 
 navian immigrants has not grown fast enough to keep pace 
 with the needs of American industry must be sought in the 
 economic conditions of the Scandinavian countries. Since 
 the opportunity eventually to secure a homestead in the 
 United States is gone, the agricultural laborer who is dis- 
 satisfied with his condition must seek employment in indus- 
 try. And here the recent industrial progress of the Scandi- 
 navian countries offers him many an opportunity at home. 
 
 The industrial development of Sweden is contempo- 
 raneous with the latest progress in engineering, which has 
 harnessed the water power furnished in abundance by her 
 mountains. The growth of Swedish industries has far out- 
 run the increase of her population. As a result, Sweden 
 has become a country of immigration. The immigration to 
 Sweden has in recent years left a surplus over emigration. 
 
 In Denmark the last fifteen years of the nineteenth cen- 
 tury witnessed a rise of the peasant farmer, due chiefly to 
 the rapid spread of co-operation in all branches of farming. 
 The progress of agriculture has attracted immigration to 
 Denmark. During every agricultural season considerable 
 numbers of Polish peasants come to work of the farms in 
 Denmark. 
 
Summary Review 17 
 
 While the wave of emigration from Great Britain and 
 Ireland to the United States has receded from the high- 
 water mark reached in 1880-1889, yet, eliminating that 
 exceptional decade, we find that during the 2O-year period 
 1890-1909, marked by the influx of immigrants from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe, the United States received more 
 immigrants from Great Britain and Ireland than during the 
 20-year period 1860-1879. Another fact that must not be 
 lost sight of is the recent development of Canada, Australia, 
 New Zealand, and South Africa, which has naturally drawn" 
 a part of the emigration from Great Britain and Ireland. 
 The policy of restriction adopted in Australia, New Zealand, 
 and South Africa has conferred a special privilege upon 
 immigrants of British nationality. On the other hand, 
 the governments of Canada and Australia are making sys- 
 tematic efforts to induce and assist immigration from the 
 mother country. That the financial assistance offered to 
 immigrants from the United Kingdom has diverted a part 
 of them from the United States is but natural. 
 
 The decline of Irish immigration began as far back as 
 1861. It rose again in the 8o's, in the turbulent years of 
 the Irish Land League agitation, and once more during the 
 past decade. That the "new immigration" to the United 
 States was not the cause of the decline of Irish immigration 
 is clear from the fact that the emigration movement from 
 Ireland to other countries lias also' declined, while, on the 
 other hand, of those Irish who did emigrate the proportion 
 destined to the United States was higher during the period 
 of the great influx of immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe than in 1876-1890, when immigration from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe was negligible. There have been 
 forces at work to reduce the number of Irish seeking to 
 better their condition away from home. The great Irish 
 unrest of the 8o's forced the British Parliament to enact 
 remedial legislation, which gave to the tenant-at-will a legal 
 title to his holding, besides reducing his rent, and converted 
 about one third of the tenants into land proprietors. These 
 
1 8 Immigration and Labor 
 
 far-reaching reforms in a country with a predominantly 
 peasant population sufficiently account for the decline of 
 emigration from Ireland. 
 
 It can be seen from this brief survey that immigration 
 from Northern and Western Europe has declined, not 
 because the condition of labor has deteriorated in the United 
 States, but because those countries have become better 
 homes for their citizens. 
 
 Another popular fallacy is the theory originated by Gen- 
 eral Walker, that the immigrants have displaced unborn 
 -generations of native Americans. It rests on no other foun- 
 dation than a computation made in 1 8 1 5 from the increase of 
 the population of the United States between 1790 and 1810. 
 During the century that has elapsed, the declining birth- 
 rate has become a world-wide social phenomenon. In the 
 Australian Commonwealth, with her vast continent as yet 
 unsettled, with a purely Anglo-Saxon population and prac- 
 tically no immigration, the decline of the birth-rate has been 
 as rapid as among Americans of native stock. Prof. Wilcox 
 has proved by an analysis of population statistics that the 
 decrease in the proportion of children began in the United 
 States as early as 1810. The native birth-rate has declined 
 with the, increase of the urban population and the relative 
 decrease of the number of farmers. The rearing of children 
 on a farm requires less of the mother's time and attention 
 than in the city. Moreover, the child on a farm begins to 
 work at an earlier age than in the city. A numerous family 
 on a farm has the advantages of a co-operative group, where- 
 as every addition td the family of the wage-earner or of the 
 salaried man with a fixed income tends to lower the family's 
 standard of living. It is significant that the decline of the 
 birth-rate is universal among those classes which are scarcely, 
 if at all, affected by immigrant competition. Their stand- . 
 ard of living is higher than that of the wage-earner. Yet it : 
 is precisely the desire to preservelhis higher standard that 
 accounts for the practice of race suicide. Granting, for the 
 sake of argument, that the absence of immigration in the 
 
Summary Review 19 
 
 past would have raised the native wage-earner's standard 
 of living to that of the middle class, it does not follow that 
 the natural increase among the native-born would have 
 sufficed to supply the needs of the rapidly expanding indus- 
 tries of the United States. 
 
 There was clearly no other source from which American i 
 industry could have drawn its labor supply than immigra- 
 tion from the countries of Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 Without the immigrants from those countries the recent 
 development of American industry would have been im- 
 possible. 
 
 An invidious distinction is drawn between the old and 
 the new immigrants by reason of the fact that the bulk of 
 the latter are incapable of any. but unskilled work. A com- 
 parative statistical study of immigration shows that the old 
 immigrants, like those of the present generation, were I 
 mostly unskilled laborers and farm hands. The proper- \ 
 tion of skilled mechanics has at no time within the past fifty 
 years been as high as one fourth of all immigrant bread- 
 winners, for the very obvious reason that the demand in the 
 American labor market has been mainly for unskilled 
 laborers. Invention of machinery has had the tendency to . 
 reduce the demand for mechanical skill, and most of that 
 demand has been supplied by native Americans. In the 
 industrial army the commissioned and non-commissioned 
 officers are outnumbered by the privates. It is a mis- 
 conception of modern industrial organization to confuse 
 lack of "skill," i. e., ignorance of a trade, with "low ef- 
 ficiency. ' ' If every immigrant were a skilled mechanic, most 
 of them would nevertheless have to accept employment as 
 unskilled laborers. The special skill of the engineer would 
 give him no superiority at loading coal over a common 
 laborer, nor would the ability to read Shakespeare in the 
 vernacular assure higher wages to a mule-driver. 
 
 The objection to the unskilled$riHsr grant is based upon . 
 the belief that because of his lower Standard 6* living he is ^ 
 satisfied with lower wages than the American or the older 
 
2O Immigration and Labor 
 
 immigrant. It is therefore taken for granted that the 
 effect of the great tide of immigration in recent years 
 has been to reduce the rate of wages or to prevent it from 
 advancing. The fallacy of this reasoning is due to the at- 
 tempt to compare the wages and standard of living of the 
 unskilled laborer with those of the skilled mechanic. In 
 order to prove that the new immigrants have introduced a 
 lower standard of living, the latter ought to be compared 
 with the standard of living of unskilled laborers in the past. 
 Housing conditions have been most dwelt upon in the dis- 
 cussion of the standard of living of the immigrant, because 
 they strike the eye of the outsider. Historical studies of 
 housing conditions show, however, that congestion was 
 recognized as a serious evil in New York City as far back as 
 the first half of the nineteenth century. The evil was not 
 confined to the foreign-born population. American-born 
 working- women lived on filthy streets in poorly ventilated 
 houses, crowding in one or two rooms which were used both 
 as dwelling and workshop. No better were the living con- 
 ditions of the daughters of American farmers in the small 
 mill towns of New England. They lived in company 
 houses, half a dozen in one attic room, without tables, or 
 chairs, or even washstands. Comparative statistics of house 
 tenancy in Boston show that in the middle of the nineteenth 
 century the tenement-house population was as numerous, 
 in proportion, as in our day. The conversion of the old 
 single-family residence into a tenement house, where a 
 whole family was jammed in every room, was productive of 
 filth. The inconvenience suffered by the people of New 
 York City during the recent strike of the street cleaners was 
 but a faint reminder of the normal conditions of the immi- 
 grant sections of New York or Boston half a century ago. 
 These conditions are a thing of the past. The typical tene- 
 ment house in the Jewish and Italian sections of New York 
 to-day is a decided improvement upon the dwellings of the 
 older immigrant races in the same sections a generation or 
 two ago. On the other hand, in the South, where many of 
 
Summary Review 21 
 
 the coal mines are operated without immigrant labor, and 
 native white Americans are employed as unskilled laborers, 
 their homes are primitive and insanitary. 
 
 It is evident that the cause of bad housing conditions isT 
 not racial, but economic. Congestion in great cities is 
 produced by industrial factors over which the immigrants 
 have no control. The fundamental cause of congestion 
 with all its attendant evils is the necessity for the wage- 
 worker to live within an accessible distance from his place 
 of work. In mining towns the mine company is usually he 
 landlord, and the mine worker has no choice in the matter of 
 housing accommodations. In so far, however, as housing 
 conditions might affect the rates of wages of native and im- 
 migrant workmen, it is the amount of rent, not the equiva- 
 lent in domestic comfort, that has to be considered. And 
 here it is found that immigrants have to pay the same rent 
 as, and often a higher rent than, native American wage- 
 earners. A certain proportion among the immigrants seek 
 to reduce their rent by taking in boarders, but the practice 
 is not universal, and the wages of the others must therefore 
 provide for the payment of normal rent. Moreover, the 
 recent immigrants are mostly concentrated in great cities, 
 where rent is high, while the native American workmen live 
 mostly in small towns with low rents. 
 
 Nor are the food standards of the recent immigrant in- 
 ferior to those of native Americans with the same income. 
 Meat, the most expensive article of food, is consumed by 
 the Slav in larger quantities than by native Americans. 
 Rent and food claim by far the greater part of a workman's 
 wages. It is thus apparent that whatever may have been 
 the immigrant's standard of living in his home country, his 
 expenditure in the United States is determined by the prices 
 ruling in the United States. Contrary to common assertion, 
 the living expenses of the native American workman in 
 small cities and rural districts are lower than those of the 
 recent immigrants in 1he great industrial centers. It is 
 therefore not the recent immigrant that is able to underbid 
 
22 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the native American workman, but it is, on the contrary, 
 the latter that is in a position to accept a cheaper wage. 
 
 There is, of course, a difference between the expenses of a 
 single and of a married workman. The necessary expenses 
 of a single man are lower than those of one who has a family 
 to support, and a large proportion of the recent immigrants 
 are either single or have left their families abroad. But, 
 while an unmarried American workman may either save or 
 spend the difference, the recent immigrant is obliged to save 
 a part of his earnings. He must repay the cost of his own 
 passage; if he has left a family at home, he must save up 
 money to pay for their passage, besides supporting them in 
 the meantime. So when the recent immigrant is seen to 
 deny himself every comfort in order to reduce his personal 
 expenses to a minimum, it is a mistake to assume that he 
 will accept a wage just sufficient to provide for his own sub- 
 sistence. The Italian section hand who lives on vegetables 
 does not save money for the railroad company. The eco- 
 nomic interests of the American wage-earner are therefore 
 not affected by the tendency of the recent immigrant to live 
 as cheaply as possible and to save as much as possible. 
 Whether he spends his wages for rent and dress, or saves his 
 money to buy steamship tickets for his family; whether he 
 invests his savings in a home in the United States or sends 
 them to his parents for improving the home farm, his wants 
 in one case are as urgent as in the other, and he must 
 demand a wage which will enable him to satisfy them. 
 
 On the other hand, though the standard of living of the 
 native or Americanized wage-earners be higher than that of 
 the new immigrants, this difference is not necessarily indica- 
 tive of a higher rate of wages: the higher standard is very 
 often maintained with the earnings of the children, whereas 
 the Southern and Eastern European immigrants are mostly 
 young people whose children have not reached working age. 
 The supposed differeneeim the standard of livin n there- 
 fore have no effect V^pon the comparative rater> .ges of 
 English-speakii "~kmen and of decent imnr : ts. 
 
Summary Review 23 
 
 But it is argued that the newly arrived immigrant must 
 have work at once and is therefore glad to accept any terms. 
 The Immigration Commission after a study of the earnings 
 of more than half a million employees in mines and manu- 
 factures, has discovered no evidence that immigrants have 
 been hired for less than the prevailing rates of wages. 
 
 The primary cause which has determined the movement 
 of wages in the United States during the past thirty years 
 has been the introduction of labor-saving machinery. The 
 effect of the substitution of mechanical devices for human 
 skill is the displacement of the skilled mechanic by the 
 unskilled laborer. This tendency has been counteracted in 
 the United States by the expansion of industry: while the* 
 ratio of skilled mechanics to the total operating force was 
 decreasing, the increasing scale of operations prevented an 
 actual reduction in numbers. Of course this adjustment did 
 not proceed without friction. While, in the long run, there 
 has been no displacement of skilled mechanics J3y unskilled 
 laborers in the industrial field as a whole, yet at certain 
 times and places individual skilled mechanics were doubtless 
 dispensed with and had to seek new employment. The 
 unskilled laborers who replaced them were naturally 
 engaged at lower wages. The fact that most of these 
 unskilled laborers were immigrants disguised the substance 
 of the change the substitution of unskilled for skilled 
 labor and made it appear as the displacement of highly- 
 paid native by cheap immigrant labor. 
 
 To prove that immigration has virtually lowered the rates 
 of wages, would require a comparative study of wages paid 
 for the same class of labor in various occupations before and 
 after the great influx of immigration. This, however, has 
 never been attempted by the advocates of restriction. In 
 fact, the -chaotic state of our wage statistics precludes any 
 but a fragmentary comparison for different periods. In a 
 general way, however, all available data for the period of 
 " the old immigration" agree in that the wages of unskilled 
 laborers, and even of some of the skilled mechanics, did not 
 
24 Immigration and Labor 
 
 fully provide for the support of the wage-earner and his 
 family in accordance with their usual standards of living. 
 The shortage had to be made up by the labor of the wife 
 and children. 
 
 If the tendency of the new immigration were to lower the 
 rate of wages or to retard the advance of wages, it should be 
 expected that wages would be lower in great cities where the 
 recent immigrants are concentrated, than in rural districts 
 where the population is mostly of native birth. All wage 
 statistics, concur, however, in the opposite conclusion. 
 Since the United States has become a manufacturing coun- 
 try average earnings per worker have been higher in the 
 cities than in the country. The same difference exists 
 within the same trades between the large and the small 
 cities. Country competition of native Americans often 
 acts as a depressing factor upon the wages of recent 
 immigrants. This fact has been demonstrated in the 
 clothing industry, in the cotton mills, in the coal mines, 
 etc. 
 
 Furthermore, if immigration tends to depress wages, 
 this tendency must manifest itself in lower average earnings 
 in States with a large immigrant population than in States 
 with a predominant native population. No such tendency, 
 however, is discernible from wage statistics. As a rule, 
 annual earnings are higher in States with a higher per- 
 centage of foreign-born workers. 
 
 The conditions in some of the leading industries employ- 
 ing large numbers of recent immigrants point to the same 
 conclusions. In the Pittsburgh steel mills the rates of wages 
 of various grades of employees have varied directly with the 
 proportion of recent immigrants. The wageL of the aristo- 
 crats of labor, none of whom are Southern or Eastern 
 Europeans, have been reduced in some cases as much as 40 
 per cent; the money wages of the skilled and semi-skilled 
 workers, two thirds of -whom are natives or old immigrants, 
 have not advanced notwithstanding the increased cost of 
 living, while the wages of the unskilled laborers, the bulk 
 
Summary Review 25 
 
 of whom are immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, have been going up. " 
 
 Another typical immigrant industry is the manufacture 
 of clothing. The clothing industry has become associated 
 in the public mind with the sweating system, and since the 
 employees are, with few exceptions, immigrants from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe, the conclusion is readily reached 
 that the root of the sweating system is in the character of 
 the new immigration. Yet the origin of the sweating sys- 
 tem preceded the Jewish clothing workers by more than half 
 a century. Throughout the second quarter of the past 
 century native American and Irish women worked in the 
 s,weat shops of New York, Boston, and Philadelphia for only 
 board and lodging, or even for board alone, depending upon 
 their families for other necessities, whereas the Jewish fac- 
 tory girls of the present day are at least self-supporting. 
 
 In the cotton mills of New England the last quarter of the 
 nineteenth century, when the operatives were practically all 
 of the English-speaking races, was a period of intermittent 
 advances and reductions in wages ; on the whole, wages re- 
 mained stationary. The first years of the present century, 
 up to the crisis of 1908, were marked by the advent of 
 the Southern and Eastern Europeans into the cotton mills, 
 and by an uninterrupted upward movement of wages. 
 The competition of the cheap American labor of the 
 Southern cotton mills, however, tends to keep down the 
 wages of the Southern and Eastern European, Armenian, 
 and Syrian immigrants employed in the New England 
 mills. 
 
 As a general rule, the employment of large numbers of 
 recent immigrants has gone together with substantial 
 advances in wages. This correlation between the move-^ " ' 
 ments of wages and immigration is not the manifestation of 
 some mysterious racial trait, but the plain working of the 
 law of supply and demand. The employment of a high^ , 
 percentage of immigrants in any section, industry, oroccupa-~ - 
 tion, is an indication of an active demand for labor in pv-.ss 
 
26 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the native supply. Absence of immigrants is a sign of 
 a dull labor market. 
 
 To be sure, the rise in wages is paralleled by a similar 
 movement of prices. The employer of labor seeks to recoup 
 the advance in wages by advancing the price of his product 
 to the consumer. When the advance in the price of manu- 
 factured products becomes general, the wage-earner as a 
 consumer is forced in effect to give up a part or all of his 
 gain in the money rate of wages. The increased cost of 
 living then stimulates further demands for advances in 
 wages. Since combinations of capital in all fields of industry 
 have reduced competition among employers of labor to a 
 minimum, the wage-earners have been at a disadvantage in 
 this continuous bargaining. In general it has been observed 
 by economists that wages, as a rule, do not rise as fast as 
 prices. That this rule holds true irrespective of immigra- 
 tion, is illustrated by the movement of wages and prices 
 during the Civil War. With the exception of the first year, 
 the period was one of prosperity in every branch of industry. 
 The wage-earners were apparently in a favorable situation. 
 The army drew hundreds of thousands of workers from 
 industrial pursuits, while immigration declined. There 
 were at that time no immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, nor was there any oversupply of unskilled labor. 
 Yet while the depreciation of the currency caused a rapid 
 increase in the cost of living, money wages did not keep 
 pace with prices. In other words, real wages decreased. 
 It must be noted that during the war a lively labor agitation 
 was going on; strikes were usually successful. Withal, 
 labor was unable to win increases in wages commensurate 
 with the increased cost of living. 
 
 Among the factors tending to depress the rate of wages 
 
 child labor holds a prominent place. The most significant 
 
 fact to be noted concerning the relation between child labor 
 
 \and immigration is the large proportion of children em- 
 
 . ployed in factories in States where there is practically no 
 
 immigrant population, whereas the lowest per cent is found 
 
Summary Review 27 
 
 in New York, which is overrun by immigrants. The 
 growth of manufacturing industries in the South being re- 
 stricted by the natural increase of her native population, the 
 manufacturers, in order to extend their operations, must 
 resort to the employment of children, as did their prede- 
 cessors in New England a century ago, before immigration 
 came to supply the needs of American industry. This situ- 
 ation is by no means confined to the South. Absence of ! 
 foreign immigration has created a demand for the labor of 
 native American children in the canneries and shoe factories 
 of rural and semi-rural Missouri. The principal induce- 
 ment for locating new shoe factories in rural sections of 
 Missouri appears to be the availability of the cheap labor 
 of native American women and children, who can underbid 
 the male immigrants employed in the shoe factories of 
 Massachusetts. On the other hand, taking the United 
 States as a whole, we find that during the ten-year period 
 from 1899 to 1909, with its unprecedented immigration, the 
 average number of children employed in factories did not 
 increase, while their relative number decreased. 
 
 An unerring measure of the effects of immigration on\ 
 labor conditions is furnished by the length of the working 
 day. Aside from the benefits of shorter hours for the physi- 
 cal and mental well-being of the wage-earner, every reduc- 
 tion of the hours of labor, even when not accompanied by 
 an increase of the daily or weekly wage, is equivalent to an 
 increase of the hourly wage. Going back to the beginnings 
 of the factory system in the United States, when the opera- 
 tives were sons and daughters of American farmers, we find 
 that the hours of labor in the factories were from sunrise 
 to sunset, the same as on the farms to-day. The retirement 
 of the native element and their replacement by Irish immi- 
 grants was followed by a reduction of the hours of labor in 
 the textile mills. In recent vears the mills have been run 
 with a polyglot help made up of representatives of all the 
 races of Southern and Eastern Europe and Asiatic Turkey. 
 Compared with the time when the operatives were mostly 
 
8 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Irish, the factory workers have again won a reduction of an 
 hour and a quarter a day. One need not take an optimistic 
 view of labor conditions in the Massachusetts textile mills 
 to recognize that fifty-four hours a week is a great stride in 
 advance since the time when the regular working day was 
 from sunrise to sunset. 
 
 The effects of the recent immigration upon the length of 
 the working day can be best observed in the State of New 
 York, which is affected by immigration more than any other 
 State in the Union. The first decade of the present century 
 has witnessed the greatest volume of immigration known in 
 the history of the United States, and the bulk of that immi- 
 gration has come from the countries of Southern and East- 
 ern Europe. And yet the reports of the factory inspectors 
 of the State of New York, covering an average of nearly a 
 . million factory employees annually, show for that decade a 
 I gradual reduction of the hours of labor in the State of New 
 I York. Comparing the city of New York with the remain- 
 der of the State, we find that the population of Southern and 
 Eastern European birth in the great city increased during 
 the same period from one sixth to about one fourth of the 
 total population, whereas in the State outside the city of 
 New York the immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe constituted in 1910 only one sixteenth of the total 
 population; yet after a decade of "undesirable immigration " 
 more than two thirds of all factory operatives in New York 
 City work ten hours or less on week days with a half holiday 
 on Saturday, whereas in the remainder of the State, with a 
 working population predominantly native, the majority 
 still work longer hours. The lower wages of tiie native 
 American wage-earners in small cities and country towns 
 might be explained by the lower cost of living, which per- 
 mits the native country worker to enjoy a greater measure 
 of comfort than the more highly paid recent immigrant 
 living in a large city. But the longer hours of the native 
 American wage-earner in the country admit of no such 
 explanation. 
 
Summary Review 29 
 
 Among the many charges against the recent immigrants 
 not the least important one is that their ignorant acquies- 
 cence in dangerous and unsanitary working conditions is a 
 menace to the safety of the older employees. The Immi- 
 gration Commission has accepted without criticism the 
 employers' defense in work accidents, viz., that the majority 
 of accidents arise from the negligence, the ignorance, and 
 inexperience of the employees. There is, however, another 
 side to the question. Many experts hold that most of the 
 risks are humanly preventable, and their continuance is due 
 to economic conditions beyond the control of the employee, 
 Effective prevention of accidents in mines presupposes a 
 carefully planned equipment involving considerable ex- 
 pense. But competition forces the mine operator to follow 
 unsafe mining methods, which inevitably result in unneces- 
 sary sacrifice of human life. It is not the carelessness of 
 the mine workers, but the carelessness of mine operators and 
 their representatives that is, according to expert opinion, the 
 cause of the high fatality rate in American mines. Similar 
 dangerous conditions once existed in France and Belgium, 
 but they were removed by stringent legislation and by an 
 effective enforcement of the law. The theory which shifts 
 the blame for accidents from the mine operator to the Slav 
 miner tends to prevent the enactment of such legislation in 
 the United States,^/ 
 
 In the iron and steel mills there is the same popular dispo- 
 sition to shift the responsibility for accidents to "the 
 ignorant foreigner," whereas expert opinion views the tre- 
 mendous speed at which the plants are run as the real cause 
 of danger. The greatest risk of death and personal injury is 
 assumed by railway trainmen, who are all either Americans 
 or natives of Northern and Western Europe. They have 
 strong organizations and could not be replaced by non- 
 English-speaking immigrants. Yet "acquiescence in dan- 
 gerous and unsanitary working conditions" appears to be 
 the general attitude of organized and unorganized workers 
 alike, irrespective of nationality. Obviously, organized 
 
30 Immigration and Labor 
 
 labor does not feel strong enough to make demands which 
 would involve large outlays by employers for safe equip- 
 ment. 
 
 Organization of labor is nowadays generally recognized 
 in the United States as the most effective of all existing 
 agencies for the increase of wages and improvement of work- 
 ing conditions. It would therefore be a cause for grave con- 
 cern if it were true, as claimed, that the recent immigrants 
 .were not organizable, and that their employment threat- 
 ened the existing labor organizations with disruption. 
 'f The fact is, however, that the origin and growth of orga- 
 nized labor in the United States are contemporaneous with 
 the period of "the new immigration," and that the immi- 
 grants from Southern and Eastern Europe are the backbone 
 of some of the strongest labor unions. A notable example 
 is the coal-mining industry, where the mine workers' organi- 
 zation has gained strength only since the Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans have become the predominant element 
 among them. One of the most troublesome problems which 
 the organization of these immigrants has had to face has 
 been the competition of the unorganized Americans of 
 
 .native stock. 
 
 "^ ^. Before 1880 all labor organizations were small in member- 
 ship and their effect upon economic conditions was negli- 
 gible. Like everywhere, during the infancy of organized 
 labor, a union would spring into existence under the impulse 
 of a strike, would flourish for a while, if successful, and would 
 soon disintegrate. The work of organization has since been 
 proceeding at an ever increasing pace. During the first 
 decade of the new immigration, 1880-1890, more labor 
 unions were organized than throughout the previous history 
 
 s-l of the United States. The majority of the trade-unionists 
 and Knights of Labor were of foreign birth, whereas the 
 native Americans contributed less Jhan their qftota to the 
 membership of labor organizations. The greatest success 
 rewarded the efforts of union organizers during the first 
 decade of the present century, the membership of labor 
 
Summary Review 31 
 
 organizations growing faster than the number of wage- 
 earners. Thus the greatest activity in the field of organi- I 
 zation coincided with the unparalleled immigration of the I 
 past decade. The best field for observation of the effects of 
 immigration upon trade-unionism is the State of New York, 
 which receives more than its proportionate share of immi- 
 grants from Southern and Eastern Europe. A comparative 
 study of trade-union statistics compiled by the New York 
 Bureau of Labor and of the federal immigration statistics 
 shows that union membership rises and falls with the rise - 
 and fall of immigration. The fluctuations of union mem- 
 bership depend upon the business situation, which likewise 
 determines the fluctuations of immigration. The harmoni- 
 ous movement of immigration and organization among 
 wage-earners is thus accounted for by the fact that both are 
 stimulated by business prosperity and discouraged by busi- 
 ness depression. 
 
 The question arises, however, whether the progress of 
 trade-unionism would not have been greater had there been 
 no immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe during 
 the past decade of industrial expansion. An answer to thil ' 
 question is furnished by the comparative growth of trade- 
 union membership in New York and in Kansas. The ratio 
 of foreign-born in Kansas has been steadily decreasing since 
 1880. At the same time Kansas has shared in the recent 
 industrial expansion. Statistics show that the relative 
 number of organized workmen is much higher in New York 
 with its large and growing Southern and Eastern European 
 population than in Kansas, where more than nine tenths of 
 the population are of native birth. 
 
 These comparisons prove that recent immigration has 
 not retarded the progress of trade-unionism, except, of 
 course, where it is the policy of the unions to exclude the 
 recent immigrants by prohibitive initiation dues and other 
 restrictive regulations intended to limit the number of com- 
 petitors within their trades. 
 
 Language is nowadays no longer a bar to organization 
 
 JL - 
 
32 Immigration and Labor 
 
 among immigrants. The membership of every union in- 
 cludes a sufficient number of men of every nationality 
 through whom their countrymen can be reached. 
 
 Many of the more recent immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe had acquired a familiarity with the prin- 
 ciples of organization in their home countries. In Italy 
 organization has lately made rapid progress not only among 
 industrial workers, but also among agricultural laborers. 
 In Russia, previous to the uprising of 1905, labor organi- 
 zations and strikes were treated as conspiracies, but the 
 revolutionary year 1905 outmatched the labor-union record 
 of any other country. The strikes of that year affected one 
 third of all the factories employing three fifths of all factory 
 workers. The total number of strikers, at a conservative 
 estimate, exceeded three and a half millions. The strikers 
 drew together wage-earners of all those nationalities which 
 make up the bulk of our immigration from the Russian Em- 
 pire: Hebrews, Poles, Lithuanians, Russians, and Ukrain- 
 ians. 1 In this connection, it is worthy of note that the 
 organizations of clothing workers in New York City, nearly 
 all of whom are Russian and Polish Jews and Italians, com- 
 prise a higher proportion of the total number employed in 
 the industry than the average trade-union in the United 
 States. 
 
 If organized labor in the United States has not succeeded 
 in welding together a majority of the wage-earners, the fault 
 is neither with immigration in general, nor with immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe in particular. The 
 primary cause is the substitution of machinery for human 
 skill, which is taking the ground from the craft union. The 
 latter, however, as a rule, does not seek to organize the un- 
 skilled laborers. Situations have arisen where the interests 
 of the craft union have been antagonistic to organization 
 among the unskilled. That organization among the unskilled j 
 
 J The revolution of 1917 has made organized labor a part of the 
 machinery of government. . 
 
Summary Review 33 
 
 is feasible, however, has been demonstrated in the coal-mining 
 industry, " - +he Lawrence strike, and in the recent strikes of 
 the steel workers. 
 
 Another obstacle to the progress of trade-unionism is that 
 the principal industries to-day are controlled by combina- 
 tions, which have reduced competition among employers 
 of labor to a minimum. In a contest of endurance between 
 a trust and a trade-union, the former is able to hold out 
 longer, since it can shift the losses to the consumers. The 
 only successful strikes against trusts have been those in 
 which the majority of the strikers were immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, viz., the strikes in the anthra- 
 cite coal mines of Pennsylvania and in the woolen mills of 
 Lawrence. 
 
 One of the reasons for the greater power of resistance 
 exhibited by the Southern and Eastern Europeans is the 
 predominance among them of men without families. 1 The 
 single European wage-earner who manages to save a portion 
 of his earnings can fall back on his savings, if necessary. 
 This relieves the pressure upon the strike fund. On the 
 other hand, the families of recent immigrants, being inured 
 to the most simple life in their home countries, can more 
 easily endure the hardships of a strike than the families of 
 native American wage-earners. The Southern and Eastern 
 European strikers are therefore able to hold out longer in a 
 wage contest than the native wage-earner. 
 
 The defeat of many strikes is charged against the immi- 
 grant, who, though supposedly too tractable under normal 
 conditions, is said to be inclined to violence when aroused. 
 Suffice it to say that strike riots are as old as strikes in the 
 United States. 
 
 1 The proportion of married men among the recent immigrants 
 employed in bituminous coal mines varied from 49.4 per cent to 77.2 per 
 cent; the proportion of married men whose families were living abroad 
 averaged 27.9 per cent for all races, varying from 19.5 to 80.4 per cent. 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, Tables 102 and 104. 
 
34 Immigration and Labor 
 
 On the other hand, however, the United Mine Workers 
 
 of America, whose members are mostly immigrants from 
 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, has put into practical opera- 
 
 | tion an industrial parliament, with separate representation 
 
 ifor employers and employees, for the regulation of the terms 
 of employment. It can not be said then "as a general 
 proposition . . . that all improvement in conditions and in- 
 creases in rates of pay have been secured in spite of the 
 presence of the recent immigrant." 1 
 
 The results of the preceding discussion can be summed up 
 as follows: 
 
 (1) Recent immigration has displaced none of the native 
 American wage-earners or of the earlier immigrants, but has 
 only covered the shortage of labor resulting from the excess 
 of the demand over the domestic supply. 
 
 (2) Immigration varies inversely with unemployment; 
 it has not increased the rate of unemployment. 
 
 (3) The standard of living of the recent immigrants is 
 not lower than the standard of living of the past generations 
 of immigrants engaged in the same occupations. Recent 
 immigration has not lowered the standard of living of Ameri- 
 cans and older immigrant wage-earners. 
 
 (4) Recent immigration has not reduced the rates of 
 wages, nor has it prevented an increase in the rates of wages ; 
 it has pushed the native and older immigrant wage-earners 
 upward on the scale of occupations. 
 
 (5) The hours of labor have been reduced contempo- 
 raneously with recent immigration: s * 
 
 (6) The membership of labor organizations has grown 
 apace with recent immigration; the new immigrants have 
 contributed their proportionate quota to the membership 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 541. Since the 
 days of the Immigration Commission another experiment in industrial 
 government, inaugurated by recent immigrants in the clothing factory 
 of Hart, Schaffner and Marx, has attracted wide notice among labor 
 leaders and social workers. 
 
Summary Review 
 
 of every labor organization which has not di. 
 against them, and they have firmly stood by their , 
 dons in every contest. 
 
 ^There is consequently no specific "immigration proble. 
 There is a general labor problem, which comprises man> 
 special problems, such as organization of labor, reduction of 
 hours of labor, child labor, unemployment, prevention of 
 work-accidents, etc. None of these problems being affected 
 by immigration, their solution can not be advanced by 
 restriction or even by complete prohibition of immigration. > 
 
 The advocates of restriction are conscious of the fact that i 
 without immigration the industrial expansion of the past^ 
 twenty years would have been impossible. But they be- 
 lieve that the pace of progress has been too fast and that 
 the interests of labor would be furthered by a slower devel- 
 opment of industry which would dispense with Southern and 
 Eastern European unskilled laborers. This was the gist of 
 the recommendations of the Immigration Commission. 
 
 The weak point in this argument is that it takes no cogni- 
 zance of the cardinal principle of modern division of labor, 
 viz., that in every industrial establishment there is a fixed 
 proportion of skilled to unskilled laborers. Were the expan- 
 sion of industry to slow down in consequence of a reduced 
 supply of unskilled labor, the demand for skilled mechanics 
 would eventually decline in proportion. The slow growth of 
 industry would tend to curtail the opportunities for advance-* 
 ment of the wage-earners who are already here. The skilled 
 crafts whose organizations favor the exclusion of unskilled 
 immigrants would be the first to suffer in consequence| 
 
 On the other hand, the unemployed could gain nothing - 
 from a slow growth of industry. Seasonal and cyclical 
 variations in the general demand for labor, as well as varia- 
 tions in the demands of individual employers, would continue 
 on a reduced scale -of national production. The mere ex- 
 clusion of immigrants will not provide employment for sail- 
 ors in the winter, or for the full winter force of a Wisconsin 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 camp in the summer; nor will it revolutionize the 
 A of fashion. In order to provide regular employment 
 ^r all workers, it would be necessary to run all industries 
 upon a common time schedule, like railway trains are run 
 on connecting lines. No plan of such a readjustment has as 
 yet been suggested by the advocates of immigration restric- 
 tion. Certainly an adjustment of the busy and slack seasons 
 of a quarter of a million factories will not spring up spon- 
 taneously from an act of Congress closing the gates against 
 immigrants. The present -crisis, which has followed a period 
 with immigration reduced to insignificant proportions, dem- 
 onstrates how ineffectual restriction of immigration would be 
 as a remedy -against unemployment resulting from cyclical 
 disturbances of capitalistic industry. 
 
 As a speculative proposition, it seems quite plausible, that 
 f if restriction of immigration resulted in a scarcity of labor, 
 employers would be forced to pay scarcity rates of wages. 
 A standing refutation of this theory is presented by the con- 
 dition which actually exists in the United States throughout 
 the agricultural sections. Few immigrants seek employment 
 on the farms. The number of Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 pean farm laborers in the United States is negligible. More- 
 over, there is a constant stream of native labor from the farms 
 to the cities, which has led to an actual decrease of the rural 
 population in many agricultural counties. Farmers generally 
 complain of scarcity of farm labor during the agricultural 
 season. Nevertheless, the wages of farm laborers are lower 
 than the wages of unskilled laborers in mines and mills where 
 recent jmmigrants predominate. Scarcity of labor has not 
 forced the farmer to pay scarcity wages, but has merely re- 
 tarded the growth of farming. 
 
 I The World War offered an opportunity to test the effects 
 pf restriction of immigration under the most favorable con- 
 ditions. The United States became the chief producer of 
 war supplies for the allied nations. ' Beginning with the spring 
 of 1916 the supply of labor in the United States fell short of 
 
Summary Review 37 
 
 the demand. The entrance of the United States into the 
 war withdrew more than two million workers from industry. 
 Officers of the American Federation of Labor and avowed 
 friends of labor were put in charge of the various war boards 
 which were entrusted with the function of regulating wages 
 in the leading industries. If the economic condition of the 
 American wage-earner could be improved by suspension of 
 immigration, its beneficial effects should have materialized 
 during the war. 
 
 Volumes of statistics on every aspect of the economic 
 situation during the war period have been published. They 
 show a growth' of production much in excess of the rate of 
 the pre-war years. This unparalleled growth of industry was 
 marked by extraordinary profits, which were far beyond 
 anything that was necessary to stimulate initiative and 
 enterprise. 
 
 At the same time, the growth of population lagged behind J 
 the industrial expansion. To meet the abnormal demand for 
 common labor caused by the cessation of immigration, the 
 Secretary of Labor, a former labor leader, was obliged to 
 suspend the law to permit mine operators and other employers 
 in the Southwest to import Mexican laborers under contract. 
 
 This abnormal condition brought about an unprecedented I 
 mobility of labor. Reports from every section of the country 
 to Bradstreefs complained of employees "constantly being 
 enticed from their jobs by competition between employers." 1 
 Employers were offering high rates of wages to union and non- 
 union workers alike. 
 
 What, f hen, was the effect of this most favorable com- 
 bination of economic factors upon the condition of the Ameri- 
 can wage worker? 
 
 In such war-time industries as munition plants, some of 
 the occupations enjoyed increases in wages more than suffi- 
 cient to compensate for the increase in the cost of living. 
 
 1 The Literary Digest, December I, 1917, P- 80. 
 
38 Immigration and Labor 
 
 On the other hand, the wages of the railroad workers, coal 
 miners, and farm laborers, lagged behind the increase in 
 j prices. On the whole, wages did not keep pace with the 
 increasing cost of living. The workers merely struggled to 
 keep their old standards of living, and even in this struggle 
 they did not always succeed. 
 
 The most telling corroboration of the decline in real wages 
 is furnished by the investigations of medical authorities, 
 which show a decided increase of the proportion of underfed 
 school children during the World War. 
 
 We have thus witnessed a repetition of the labor conditions 
 
 which prevailed during the Civil War. This lagging of wages 
 
 /behind the advancing cost of living cannot be explained by 
 
 i the alleged submissiveness of the immigrant wage- workers, 
 
 Who are said to be willing to acquiesce in the terms offered 
 
 to them by the employers. The statistics of strikes during 
 
 the World War show that during the three years 1916-1918 
 
 the number of strikes per year was more than twice the 
 
 annual average for the period from 1881 to 1905. More than 
 
 four fifths of the war-time strikes were led by unions. The 
 
 annual average number of strikers rose to the unprecedented 
 
 figure of 1,310,000. Moreover, during the war, the principle 
 
 of collective bargaining was recognized, under the pressure 
 
 of the government, by all employers engaged on government 
 
 orders or in the production of essentials. 
 
 That the foreign worker can not be held responsible for the 
 decline of real wages is further proved by the fact that the 
 real wages of common laborers in the iron and steel industry, 
 most of whom are foreign born, went up, whereas those of 
 locomotive firemen, most of whom are native-born Ameri- 
 cans, declined to a point much below the minimum budget 
 under American standards. 
 
 Among the potent factors in the decline of real wages must 
 
 / be noted the movement of labor from agriculture to urban 
 
 1 industries. As a result, agricultural "production during the 
 
 war remained almost stationary, while the demand for bread- 
 
Summary Review 39 
 
 stuffs was increased by exports abroad. The big interests 
 which control the produce market were thereby enabled 
 to raise the prices of food. What the wage-earner gained in i 
 money wages he was forced to surrender in the higher prices j 
 of necessities of life. . 
 
 Let us now examine what were the substitutes for immi- 
 grant labor during the war years. The movement of workers 
 from agriculture to urban industries has already been ad- 
 verted to. Public attention was attracted by the migration! 
 of Negroes from the agricultural South to the industrialj 
 North. The volume of that migration is officially estimated 
 at nearly half a million. Agricultural regions of the Southern 
 states began to suffer for want of the Negro worker. Another 
 substitute for immigrant labor was found in the increased 
 nr\\nyr$er\t QJ jwmrTen^aidchildrer>. The main"torce which 
 was driving childrenlnto inclustry r was the excessive cost of 
 living. Labor commissioners and factory inspectors com- 
 plained of the difficulty experienced during the war years in 
 administering child-labor laws. The scarcity of adult labor 
 made the employer ready to take minors into his employ. 
 
 What, then, is the outlook in the ligl^of the experience of 
 labor in the late war? We are passmg* 'through one of the 
 cyclical disturbances of modern industry with Jtheir attend- 
 ant acute unemployment. But this ericas will-be over, and 
 American industry wiH~resume. s its usual course. If restric- 
 tion of immigration is to become the settled policy of the 
 United States, substitutes for immigrant labor will be sought. 
 
 The mines and mills of the Southern states which have 
 failed to attract immigrants utilize the labor of farmers and 
 their sons. The millions of tenant-farmers offer great pos- 
 sibilities as an industrial reserve available during the winter 
 months. The farm being their main source of subsistence, 
 they have been willing to offer their labor during the idle 
 winter months more cheaply than freshly landed immigrants. 
 The efforts of trade-union organizers among this class of 
 English-speaking workers have met with scant success. The 
 
39 a Immigration and Labor 
 
 substitution of the cheap labor of the American farmer foi 
 the labor of the Slav or Italian immigrant, would tend to 
 weaken the unions and to keep down wages. A stimulated 
 movement of labor from the farm to the factory would check 
 the growth of farming; the prices of foodstuffs would rise in 
 consequence, which would tend to offset the advantages to 
 the wage-earners from a possible rise of money wages. 
 
 The discontinuance of fresh supplies of immigrant labor 
 for the mills and factories of New England would give a 
 new impetus to the establishment of factories in the South, 
 where there is an abundant supply of child labor. 
 
 Still, should all the substitutes for immigration prove in- 
 adequate, it does not necessarily follow that scarcity prices 
 would rule in the American labor market. It must be borne 
 in mind that capital is international. Billions of American 
 capital are already invested in foreign enterprises. Hereto- 
 fore these investments could not compare with the profits of 
 American industries annually reinvested at home/ If, how- 
 ever, a permanent scarcity of labor were created in the 
 United States, more American capital would seek investment 
 abroad. The increased investment of American capital in 
 the industrial development of foreign countries, with cheap 
 labor, must eventually react upon labor conditions in the 
 United States. Certain of the most important American in- 
 dustries depend in part upon the export trade. A scarcity 
 of labor in the United States would induce many American 
 manufacturers to follow the example of their European com- 
 petitors, who have found it more profitable to establish fac- 
 tories in foreign countries than to export their products to 
 those countries. It is learned from an official report of the 
 Commercial Secretary of the British Embassy in Berlin, that 
 arrangements have been in progress between American capi- 
 talists and German corporations, looking toward the invest- 
 ment of American capital in German industry. There are 
 other reports to the same effect. Such an emigration of 
 American capital would materially affect the export trade of 
 
Summary Review 
 
 the United States and eventually cut off the avenues of em-- 
 ployment for a number of American wage-earners. 
 
 It is evident that while restriction of immigration can limit 
 the supply of labor, It is powerless to prevent a corresponding 
 limitation of the demand for labor. 
 
 The true cause of the decline of real wages during the late 
 war is to be found in the fact that advances in wages are the 
 outcome of the slow process of. collective bargaining, with 
 occasional industrial warfare, whereas the prices of commodi- 
 ties are controlled by monopolistic combinations, which 
 promptly shift every advance in wages to the consumer. 
 Thus the rise of wages in one industry or occupation is, in 
 effect, charged up to the working class as a whole. What is 
 wanted in order to secure to the worker a real advance in 
 wages is regulation of profits in the interest of the consumers, 
 of whom the wage-earners are the most numerous element. 
 Restriction of the supply of labor does not touch the problem 
 of price control. Immigration laws can prevent the American 
 capitalist from employing foreign labor in the United States. 
 But he may find it as profitable to employ the same labor in 
 Europe ;n the manufacture of goods for the world market. 
 The reduction of the supply of labor will be neutralized by a 
 reduction of the demand for labor in the United States. 
 
PART II. 
 
 TOPICAL ANALYSIS 
 CHAPTER I 
 
 STATEMENT OF THE QUESTION 
 
 A STUDY of the immigration question involves an ex- 
 amination of every important phase of American eco- 
 nomic, political, and social life. There is scarcely an ailment 
 of our body politic that is not diagnosed in prose and 
 in verse as the effect of unrestricted immigration. The 
 immigrants are blamed for unemployment, female and child 
 labor, the introduction of machinery, unsafe coal mines, 
 lack of organization among wage-earners, congestion in 
 great cities, industrial crises, inability to gain a controlling 
 interest in stock corporations, J pauperism, crime, insanity, 
 race suicide, gambling, the continental Sunday, parochial 
 schools, atheism, political corruption, municipal misrule. 
 The latest count in this long indictment is the McNamara 
 conspiracy, which a noted sociologist has somehow connec- 
 ted with unrestricted immigration. 2 Not only has "recent 
 immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe" lowered 
 the American standard of living, but it threatens to lower 
 "the average stature of the American. "3 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 16, p. 655. 
 * Prof. E. A. Ross, in The Survey, December 30, 1911, p. 1425. 
 Robert Hunter: Poverty, p. 269. 
 
 40 
 
Statement of the Question 41 
 
 It is conceded that in the past immigration has been a 
 material factor in the economic development of the United 
 States. It is claimed, however, that the new immigrant 
 races are of a different social type lacking the sturdy quali- 
 ties of the old immigration. * ' In the early years of immigra- 
 tion, when it was difficult, if not actually dangerous, to come 
 to the United States, there was a natural selection of the 
 best and hardiest inhabitants of the old world, men willing 
 to risk their all in going to a new country." x . The pioneers 
 of those days were eager for an opportunity to develop 
 the untouched resources of a new land and to advance 
 the march of civilization into the wilderness. The 
 new immigrant, on the contrary, is attracted by the 
 glamor of the city. To be sure, a large percentage of the 
 new immigration comes from the farming sections of 
 Europe ; but brought up, as they are, amidst the congestion 
 of the small agricultural towns of the old world, these new 
 immigrants recoil at the isolation of the American farm and 
 prefer to crowd in the congested districts of the large manu- 
 facturing cities. 
 
 The cure for the evils of immigration upon which all seem 
 to be agreed is some method of selection which would admit 
 all desirable immigrants and keep out the "undesirable." 
 There is, however, no authoritative definition of a "de- 
 sirable" and an "undesirable " immigrant. Mr. Prescdtt F. 
 Hall, Secretary of the Immigration Restriction League, 
 regards as "undesirable immigration" that " which .fe ig- 
 norant of a trade," 2 while another writer maintains that 
 the races having the highest percentages of unskilled 
 laborers are the most desirable, because they do not com- 
 pete with American mechanics, but men who are "skilled in 
 tailoring, shoemaking, baking, or other trades which do not 
 require much physical strength ... are undesirable immi- 
 grants," because "they enter into direct competition with 
 
 1 John Mitchell : Organized Labor, p. 1 77. 
 
 'Prescott F. Hall: "Selection of Immigration." Annals of the 
 American Academy of Social and Political Science, July, 1904, P- i?5. 
 
& Immigration and Labor 
 
 the American mechanic." 1 Again Mr. Hall would treat 
 as "undesirable immigration" that "which is averse to 
 country life and tends to congregate in the slums of large 
 cities," though "if our recent immigrants were able and 
 willing to go to the West and South, these States do not 
 want them." 2 Along with the Southeastern European 
 immigrant who is accordingly not wanted either in the large 
 cities, or in the agricultural West and South, the same 
 author would class as "undesirable" all immigration 
 "which fails to assimilate in a reasonable time." 3 
 
 Prof. Mayo-Smith is more specific in his definition and 
 favors the selection of immigrants with a view, among other 
 things, to the preservation of the "social morality of the 
 Puritans." 4 
 
 With respect to assimilation, conditions are said to have 
 undergone a material change. The old immigrants, scat- 
 tered amidst the native American population, were quickly 
 assimilated. Moreover, they were practically all of Teuton 
 and Celtic stock and came from countries with a represen- 
 tative form of government. The recent immigrants, on the 
 other hand, have had no training in self-government at 
 home, and being herded together in foreign colonies, out of 
 touch with native Americans, they are incapable of assimi- 
 lation and present a growing danger to the integrity of 
 American democratic institutions. 5 
 
 According to some students, this country is facing a new 
 
 x Dr. Allan McLaughlin: "Distrust of the Immigrant." Popular 
 Science Monthly, January, 1903, p. 232. 
 
 2 Prescott F. Hall, loc. cit., pp. 175, 179. * Ibid., p. 175. 
 
 * Richmond Mayo-Smith: Emigration and Immigration, p. 5. 
 
 sA writer, discussing the "perils" of "un-American immigration* 
 in 1894, gave warning that "if foreign immigration continues at the 
 present rate and such immigration continues to come from Middle, 
 Southern, and Northeastern Europe, in 1900 the Anglo-Saxon and 
 Anglo-Saxon institutions will no longer J&e the dominant powers in 
 moulding American life and legislation." Rena M. Atchison, Un- 
 American Immigration: Its Present and Future Perils, p. 148. (Chicago 
 1894.) 
 
Statement of the Question 43 
 
 race problem, similar to the negro problem. In the opinion 
 of a member of the Immigration Commission the Southern 
 Italian is not "a white man," nor is the Syrian. 1 The 
 presence of these races in large numbers among the working 
 forces of our mines and mills has attached a social stigma to 
 certain occupations; as a result of this race prejudice the 
 native American workmen have withdrawn from those 
 employments where they must work side by side with recent 
 arrivals and overcrowd the less remunerative, but more 
 respectable occupations. 2 
 
 Still the fact is that while the root of all evil is sought in 
 the racial make-up of the new immigration, as contrasted 
 with the old, every complaint against the immigrants from 
 Eastern and Southern Europe is but an echo of the com- 
 plaints which were made at an earlier day against the then 
 new immigration from Ireland, Germany, and even from 
 England. As observed by the Industrial Commission a 
 decade ago, "on the whole, it does not seem that the newer 
 immigration offers any greater or more serious problems 
 than the old, except in so far as they add to the total 
 numbers . " 3 A retrospective view of immigration will show 
 the problems presented by a polyglot population to be by 
 no means peculiar to our own day. If "assimilation" is 
 taken to mean the substitution of the English language in 
 daily intercourse for the mother tongue of the immigrant, 
 then a century of experience proves it to be an unattainable 
 ideal. But, if "assimilation" means an understanding of 
 
 1 Hearings before the House Committee on Immigration and Natural- 
 ization. 6ist Congress. Testimony of Hon. John L. Burnett, of Ala- 
 bama, p. 407. In 1885, in reply to inquiries sent out by the Iowa 
 Bureau of Labor Statistics, a laboring man complained that "the 
 Bohemians . . . will get a job in preference to a white man." (VI. 
 Biennial Report, Iowa Bureau of Labor Statistics, p. 189.) Since that 
 time the Bohemians have been advanced in the publications of the 
 Immigration Restriction League to a place among the "desirable" im- 
 migrants from Northern and Western Europe. 
 
 2 Jenks and Lauck: The Immigration Problem, pp. 75-76- 
 a Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 491. 
 
44 Immigration and Labor 
 
 American institutions, it will readily occur to the student 
 that one of the standard works on the constitutional history 
 of the United States was written in German by von Hoist, 
 an alumnus of a Russian university, and another standard 
 book on the organization of American political parties was 
 written in French by Ostrogorsky, a Russian Jew. The 
 politician who comes in closest personal contact with the 
 mass of citizenship has long since adjusted himself to the 
 conditions created by immigration and finds no difficulty 
 in presenting the issues and the candidates of his party to a 
 mixed constituency in a variety of languages. Moreover, 
 a deeper insight into the social life of the immigrant will dis- 
 cover powerful forces making for social assimilation, in those 
 very institutions which are popularly frowned upon as 
 tending to perpetuate the isolation of the foreigner from 
 American influences. The newspaper printed in a foreign 
 language is virtually a sign of Americanization; the Lithu- 
 anian peasant at home had no newspaper in his own 
 language; the demand for a newspaper has grown on 
 American soil. That it apparently serves its purpose, is 
 conceded by prominent advocates of restriction. 1 The 
 theater where the immigrant sees a play produced in his 
 mother tongue is likewise the outgrowth of the democratic 
 spirit of American social life ; the theater in Eastern Europe 
 caters only to the upper classes. The numerous foreign- 
 speaking organizations owe their existence to the political 
 freedom of the United States. It is through all these social 
 agencies using his native tongue as a medium of communi- 
 cation, that the immigrant who is not a scholar is enabled 
 to partake of the advantages of American civilization. 
 
 It is realized by the clear-sighted advocates of restriction 
 that "too rnuch emphasis, in the discussion of immigration, 
 within recent years, has been placed upon the social and 
 political results of recent immigration. The problem at 
 
 1 "So large a number of periodicals are published in various foreign 
 tongues that it is by no means essential that the immigrant read Eng- 
 lish. " Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 32. 
 
Statement of the Question 45 
 
 present is really fundamentally an industrial one." 1 The 
 reason the appeals for restriction to-day find a more favor- 
 able hearing than in the days of the Know-Nothing agita- 
 tion, is the growth of organized labor, which demands 
 restriction of immigration as an extension of the protective 
 principle to the home market in which "hands" the 
 laborer's only commodity are offered for sale. All doc- 
 trinaire theories of a civic character are accepted by orga- 
 nized labor in so far as they may be helpful in its campaign 
 for restriction of immigration. The real attitude of orga- 
 nized labor, however, is candidly stated in the testimony 
 of Mr. Roe, representing the railroad brotherhoods, before 
 the House Committee on Immigration and Naturaliza- 
 tion: "Every foreign workman who comes into this 
 country takes the place of some American workingman who 
 wants higher wages and a higher standard of living than the 
 foreigner." 2 
 
 All opposition to restriction of immigration is viewed with 
 suspicion by organized labor, as emanating from the employ- 
 ing class or from the steamship companies, which are hiding 
 selfish interests under a cloak of humanitarianism. This 
 view overlooks the millions of foreign-born wage-earners 
 who are bound by family ties with millions of workers across 
 the sea and want them to share in the opportunities which 
 this country holds out to the immigrant for bettering his 
 economic and social conditions. 3 Their appeal from the 
 present-day policy of restriction to old American traditions 
 springs from personal affection and friendship. 
 
 It must be understood, however, that the United States 
 no longer recognizes the Kantian "ideal demand of the new 
 
 1 Ibid., p. 197. 
 
 a H. R. 6ist. Congress. Hearings before Committee on Immigra- 
 tion and Naturalization, p. 254. 
 
 s The claim of the pessimists, that the condition of the immigrant 
 workman in the United States is to-day no better than in his native 
 country (Robert Hunter: Poverty, p. 280), is refuted by the millions, 
 of European workers who come to this country to stay and send for 
 their relatives. 
 
46 Immigration and Labor 
 
 law of nations," x that the individual may have the freedom 
 of the world to choose his domicil, regardless of state boun- 
 daries. The enactment of the Chinese exclusion law signa- 
 lized a reversion of the United States to the old doctrine of 
 sovereignty, which invests the state with the absolute right 
 to exclude aliens from its territory. In opposition to the 
 cosmopolitan theory underlying the free immigration policy 
 of the past, the policy of restriction has elaborated its own 
 social philosophy in the following words of Mr. John 
 Mitchell: 
 
 To a large extent the progress of nations can best be secured by the 
 policy of seclusion and isolation. By means of barriers which regulate, 
 but do not prohibit, immigration, the various countries of Europe and 
 America can individually work out their salvation, and a permanent 
 increase in the efficiency and remuneration of the workers of the world 
 can thus be obtained. By the maintenance of these barriers the best 
 workingmen in each country can rise to the top, and the great mass of 
 the workingmen can secure a larger share of the wealth produced. 2 
 
 It goes without saying that this theory of progress can 
 lay no claim to originality, "the policy of seclusion and 
 isolation" having been consistently followed for many 
 centuries by China. 
 
 Without venturing, however, into the realm of sociologi- 
 cal speculation, and allowing that if ' ' every foreign work- 
 man who comes into this country takes the place of some 
 American workingman" immigration ought to be pro- 
 hibited, the unprejudiced student of the immigration ques- 
 tion will demand proof that the premises are true. When a 
 million workers are reported to be out of employment and 
 an equal number of immigrants are shown to have been 
 admitted during the same year, the man in the street is apt 
 to jump to the conclusion that the new arrivals have dis- 
 
 1 J. C. Bluntschli: Die Bedeutung und die Fortschritte des modern en 
 Volkerrechts, p. 36. _ 
 
 a John Mitchell: Organized Labor, p. 181. It is stated on p. viii 
 of the book that it has been written in co-operation with Dr. Walter 
 E. Weyl. 
 
Statement of the Question 47 
 
 placed the native workmen or the older immigrants. On 
 closer scrutiny, however, this superficial conclusion may 
 prove wholly unwarranted. To take but one illustration, 
 the presence of a few thousand unemployed sailors in Buf- 
 falo during the winter months is no proof of an oversupply of 
 sailors during the navigation season or of an overstocked 
 labor market in general. The emigration of all Slav and 
 Italian surface laborers employed during the summer in the 
 iron mines of the Lake Superior region would not create a 
 single job for the unemployed sailors in the winter. On the 
 contrary, the reduction of the working force in the mines 
 during the season which is most favorable for their operation 
 would have the effect of reducing the volume of iron ore 
 carried on the lakes, in consequence of which a number of 
 sailors could be dispensed with in the summer. It is quite 
 obvious that the effects, if any, of immigration upon unem- 
 ployment cannot be determined by deductive reasoning. 
 The same is true of the standard of living, etc. 
 
 In order to bring to light all the facts respecting immigra' 
 tion, a commission was created in 1907 by an act of Con' 
 gress. The results of the Commission's investigations will 
 next be considered. 
 
CHAPTER II 
 
 THE REPORT OF THE IMMIGRATION COMMISSION 
 
 THE most valuable contribution of the Immigration 
 Commission to the discussion of immigration is the 
 conclusion that it should be considered "primarily as an 
 economic problem. ' ' x This statement of the question takes 
 it out of the domain of conflicting, more or less specula- 
 tive, social theories and permits of its consideration on the 
 solid basis of measurable economic realities. 
 
 Of the forty-two volumes of the Commission's report, 
 thirty-one contain primary facts directly or indirectly 
 related to the economic aspects of immigration. 2 
 
 The Commission has unanimously recommended restric- 
 tion of immigration, the only dissenting opinion being con- 
 fined to methods of restriction. There are few people who 
 will go beyond the conclusions of the Commission and 
 undertake the task of examining the evidence, presumably 
 stored up in its voluminous report. The lay public will 
 assume that the unanimous conclusions were reached after 
 mature deliberation over the evidence collected by the 
 Commission. An illuminating sidelight upon the supposed 
 connection between its recommendations and its statistics 
 is thrown by ex-Congressman William S. Bennet's dissenting 
 opinion, which contains the statement that the report of the 
 Commission was finally adopted "within a half hour of the 
 
 1 -Reports of the Immigration Commission,_yol. I, p. 25. 
 
 8 Volumes 3, 4, 6-28, 34, 35, 37, and 40. The remaining portion of 
 the report deals with ethnography, education, legislation, etc., and two 
 of the volumes are summaries of the whole. 
 
 48 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 49 
 
 time" when, under the law, it had to be filed, which left "no 
 time for the preparation of an elaborate dissent." It is 
 legitimate to question under the circumstances whether the 
 members of the Commission had the opportunity, amidst 
 their manifold duties, to examine the manuscript of the 
 forty volumes, which did not leave the printing office until 
 more than a year after the Commission had ceased to exist. 
 Apparently, they had before them merely the summary sub- 
 mitted for the Commission's approval by its experts. The 
 unanimity of the Commission thus invests its conclusions 
 with no other authority than the scientific weight of the 
 statistical and descriptive reports of its experts. The most 
 important part of the reports, viz. " Immigrants in Indus- 
 tries" (vols. 6-25), "was prepared under the direction of 
 the Commission" by one expert, Prof. W. Jett Lauck (of 
 course, with the assistance of a staff of field agents and 
 clerks). The student is, therefore, free to judge the reports 
 of the Commission by the same canons as other official 
 statistical publications. The Commission finds: 
 
 That the numbers of recent immigrants "are so great and 
 the influx is so continuous that even with the remarkable 
 expansion of industry during the past few years there has 
 been created an oversupply of unskilled labor, and in some 
 of the industries this is reflected in a curtailed number of 
 working days and a consequent yearly income among the 
 unskilled workers which is very much less than is indicated 
 by the daily wage rates paid." 
 
 That the standard of living of "the majority of the 
 employees . . . is so far below that of the native American 
 or older immigrant workman that it is impossible for the 
 latter to successfully compete with them." That "they are 
 content to accept wages and conditions which the native 
 American and immigrants of the older class had come to 
 regard as unsatisfactory . . . and as a result that class of 
 employees was gradually replaced." 
 
 That the new immigrants have in some degree "lowered 
 the American standard of living." 
 
50 Immigration and Labor 
 
 That a "characteristic of the new immigrants is the 
 impossibility of successfully organizing them into labor 
 unions. Several attempts at organization were made, but 
 the constant influx of immigrants to whom prevailing con- 
 ditions seemed unusually favorable contributed to the fail- 
 ure to organize." 
 
 That "the competition of these immigrants . . . has 
 kept conditions in the semi-skilled and unskilled occupations 
 from advancing. ' ' x 
 
 Every one of the preceding conclusions involved a com- 
 parison of the present conditions with the past. Still it is 
 only as a rare exception that fragments of statistical infor- 
 mation relating to the earlier period of American industrial 
 history can be found in the numerous volumes of the reports 
 of the Immigration Commission. No attempt has been 
 made to utilize the vast statistical material collected by the 
 State bureaus of labor statistics since the establishment of 
 the Massachusetts Bureau in 1 869. This is very much to be 
 regretted. There is no other nation in the world that ex- 
 pends so much for the collection of statistical data and so little 
 for their analysis as the United States. An index prepared 
 by the United States Bureau of Labor to the publications of 
 the State labor bureaus up to 1902 fills a volume. The data 
 contained in these publications were collected at great cost 
 during a period of years, but were for the most part pub- 
 lished in an undigested form. This defect is the result of the 
 prevailing policy of official statistical institutions to elimi- 
 nate as far as practicable all interpretations of their statis- 
 tics in order to escape the suspicion of partisanship. A 
 Congressional commission, however, is free from such limi- 
 tations, its very purpose being to draw conclusions and 
 make recommendations which are of necessity open to 
 controversy. A perusal of the single volume devoted to 
 immigration in the report of President McKinley's Indus- 
 trial Commission shows what a storehouse of original data 
 is available at small cost in the files of official publications 
 ' x Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 38, 39. 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 51 
 
 of States and municipalities. The Immigration Com- 
 mission with its vastly greater resources had the oppor- 
 tunity to make a contribution of inestimable value to the 
 study of the economic and social conditions of the 
 American people at the period of the greatest migration in 
 the history of the world. Unfortunately the Commission 
 expended all its efforts in search for new material, with 
 the result, as candidly admitted by Prof. H. Parker Willis, 
 "the editorial adviser" in the final preparation of its re- 
 port, that the thirty-one volumes have added a fresh 
 stock of ill-digested statistics to that previously accumu- 
 lated. 1 
 
 Of what value are the tables showing the rate of unem- 
 ployment of a limited number of selected families when the 
 censuses of 1890 and 1900 have collected and published such 
 data for all bread-winners in the United States? 
 
 The fact that the wage-earners in some industries were 
 unemployed some part of the year covered by the Com- 
 mission is alone insufficient to support the conclusion that 
 the number of working days has been "curtailed," without 
 a comparison of the number of working days in the same 
 industries for a series of years. "Racial displacement" 
 prominently figures in the tables of contents of every vol- 
 ume and in the subheads of every chapter dealing with the 
 condition in the manufacturing and mining industries, but 
 an inspection of the statistical tables discloses no evidence 
 of actual ' ' displacement. ' ' 
 
 One example may serve as an illustration. The changes 
 in the population of Birmingham, Alabama, have been the 
 subject of the following commentary: 
 
 1 "With so much actually collected in the way of detailed data, and 
 with but scant time in which to summarize these data, lacking, more- 
 over, a sufficient number of trained writers and statisticians to study 
 the information acquired and to set it down with a due proportion of 
 properly guarded inferences, it is a fact that much of the Commission's 
 information is still undigested, and is presented in a form which affords 
 no more than a foundation for the work of future inquirers. " H. Parker 
 Willis in The Survey of January 7, 1911, p. 57 1 - 
 
52 Immigration and Labor 
 
 It is even more significant, however, that with the exception of the 
 Welsh and Norwegians there was a falling off in numbers from the coun- 
 tries of Great Britain and Northern Europe in 1900 as contrasted with 
 1890, the increase in the foreign-born population during the ten years 
 1890-1900 practically all arising from the arrival of races from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe. 1 
 
 The numbers which have given occasion to the preceding 
 remarks were as follows: 
 
 Place of birth 1890 igoo. 
 
 England. .. 
 
 258 
 
 233 
 
 Germany . . 
 
 450 
 
 446 
 
 Ireland.... 
 
 245 
 
 218 
 
 Scotland. . . 
 
 53 
 
 52 
 
 Sweden. . . . 
 
 49 
 
 16 
 
 It will be observed that the total "falling off in numbers" 
 amounted to 33 Swedes, 27 Irish, 25 English, 4 Germans, 
 and I Scotch in all, 90 persons in ten years. At the same 
 time the native-born population increased by as many as 
 12,113 persons, while the total increase "from the arrival 
 of races from Southern and Eastern Europe " was less than 
 2 14 persons. Why should the loss of the 90 natives of Great 
 Britain and Northern Europe be interpreted as their dis- 
 placement by arrivals from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 rather than by native Americans? Moreover, the rate of 
 mortality among those nationalities, except the Swedes, 
 must have reduced their numbers by at least one sixth in ten 
 years, which is more than twice their actual falling-off and 
 suggests that there must have been some increase by immi- 
 gration from the same sources. So the actual falling-off 
 was confined to the Swedes, who if all alive were leaving 
 Birmingham at the rate of three individuals per year. Was 
 the annual loss of three Swedes "significant" enough for a 
 city whose population increased 50 per cent from 1890 to 
 1900 to be noted as evidence of "racial displacement"? 
 
 "The impossibility of successfully organizing" the new 
 immigrants "into labor unions" cannot be proved without 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 159. 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 53 
 
 statistics of union membership. The Commission has com- 
 piled no statistical table showing the growth of labor unions 
 in various trades during the period of recent immigration. 
 The data collected by the Commission as a part of its study 
 of households are too meager and fragmentary to be of any 
 value. 
 
 The following table and commentary are a fair specimen 
 of the Commission's trade-union. statistics: 1 
 
 TABLE 233. 
 
 AFFILIATION WITH TRADE-UNIONS OF MALES 21 YEARS OF AGE OR OVER 
 WHO ARE WORKING FOR WAGES, BY GENERAL NATIVITY AND RACE 
 OF INDIVIDUAL. 
 
 (Study of households.) 
 
 
 Number 
 
 Affiliated 
 
 with trade-unions 
 
 General nativity and race of individual 
 
 complete 
 data 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Native-born of native father white 
 Native-born of foreign father, by 
 race of father: 
 
 47 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 O.O 
 
 (a* 
 
 
 j 
 
 
 (a) 
 
 Irish 
 
 I 
 
 
 (a) 
 
 Polish 
 
 2 
 
 
 (a) 
 
 Foreign-born: 
 Croatian 
 
 24.O 
 
 2 
 
 .8 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 1-9 
 
 Irish 
 
 II 
 
 
 (<0 
 
 Polish 
 
 64 
 
 
 .0 
 
 Slovenian 
 
 I 
 
 
 (a) 
 
 ' Total 
 
 424 
 
 I 
 
 .7 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total native-born of foreign father 
 Total native-born . ...... 
 
 7 
 
 54 
 
 
 
 w 
 
 .0 
 
 Total foreign-born. 
 
 170 
 
 3 
 
 .8 
 
 
 
 
 
 (a) Not computed, owing to small number involved. 
 
 The above table disposes the significant fact that an exceedingly 
 small proportion of employees in Kansas City of foreign birth, and 
 none of native birth, are affiliated with labor organizat/Vni. 
 
 Ibid., vol. 13, p. 300. 
 
54 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The fact that the field agents of the Commission in a 
 study of households, not of trade-unions happened to come 
 across three trade-unionists in a city of the size of Kansas 
 City, is considered sufficient to justify the conclusion that 
 "an exceedingly small proportion of employees in Kansas 
 City . . . are affiliated with trade-unions "! Another table 
 brings out the "affiliation with trade-unions" of one South 
 Italian wage-earner among 668 householders duly "classified 
 by nativity and race of individual." * 
 
 When a single trade-unionist in an unorganized mill town 
 is enlarged into an "exhibit by general nativity and race of 
 individual," one cannot help wondering that the economic 
 data of the Commission have been compressed within the 
 small compass of thirty-one volumes. 
 
 Coming to the standard of living, it is clearly insufficient 
 to compare the sections inhabited by English-speaking 
 skilled mechanics and their families with the settlements of 
 the unskilled Slav laborers, with a view to showing that the 
 former present a better appearance than the latter. The 
 housing conditions of the new immigrants should be com- 
 pared with those of the Irish and German unskilled laborers 
 a generation ago, in order to support the conclusion that the 
 former have "introduced a lower standard." 
 
 The statistics of earnings classified by race and nativity 
 are spread over hundreds of tables, yet they are vitiated by 
 the absence of a classification by occupations. The only con- 
 clusion that can be drawn from these statistics is that the 
 weekly or annual earnings of the new immigrants are, as a 
 rule, lower than those of the native wage-earners or the older 
 immigrants. But when this information is collated with 
 the fact that the new immigrants are mostly employed in 
 unskilled occupations, while the native Americans and for- 
 eign-born employees of the older class have risen on the scale 
 
 1 Ibid., vol. 8, p. 390, Table 286. A similar table comprising two 
 Polish trade-unionists among 441 heads of households will be found in 
 the same volume on p. 765, Table 515, and another in vol. n, p. 701, 
 Table 38. 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 55 
 
 of occupations, it is readily seen that the hundreds of tables 
 show nothing beyond the fact that supervisory positions 
 and skilled trades are more remunerative than unskilled 
 labor. It was hardly necessary to expend much time and 
 labor in order to establish this fact which is a matter of 
 common knowledge. To justify the conclusions of the 
 Commission, proof was wanted that the rates of wages of 
 the new immigrants in specified occupations were lower 
 than those paid to native workmen in the same occupations 
 and in the same localities. No such proof was produced ; on 
 the contrary, the Commission found that, as a matter of fact, 
 the new immigrants ' ' were not, as a rule, engaged at lower 
 wages than had been paid to the older workmen for the same 
 class of labor/' * The numerous tables showing variations in 
 weekly earnings by race are therefore meaningless. 
 
 The popular prejudice against the new immigrant races 
 justified an unbiased comparative study of their social and 
 economic conditions in the United States 2 . Unfortunately 
 the experts and investigators of the Commission were them- 
 selves so completely under the sway of the popular senti- 
 ment that they perceived the effect of race differences even 
 in small variations of the number of mine accidents, where 
 the element of chance called for the exercise of extreme 
 caution in drawing conclusions. The following example is 
 typical of the generalizations which abound in the reports 
 of the Commission. In the year 1907 there were 75 fatal 
 and non-fatal accidents among the Lithuanians and 139 
 among the Poles employed by one anthracite coal company. 
 As the Lithuanians were somewhat more numerous than the 
 Poles, the following conclusion is drawn in the report: 
 
 The differences between the Lithuanian and Polish figures, after 
 
 1 Reports, vol. I, p. 38. 
 
 a "In studying the immigration situation in Europe the Commission 
 was not unmindful of the fact that the widespread apprehension in the 
 United States relative to immigration is chiefly due to this change in 
 the character of the movement of population from Europe in recent 
 years. " Ibid., vol. 4, P- I2 - 
 
56 Immigration and Labor 
 
 making due allowance for error in both cases, is still so great that it 
 gives ground for the inference that here a real race difference is exposed. 
 When it is remembered in how many other instances in this report 
 tables have shown a superiority of the Lithuanians over the Poles, the 
 conclusion gathers strength that the former show greater skill and care- 
 fulness in their work. 1 
 
 In Lawrence, Massachusetts, however, "the Lithuanians 
 are said to resemble the Poles in their industrial character- 
 istics, but are thought to be less intelligent or at any rate more 
 illiterate." 2 The average percentage of illiteracy among 
 the Lithuanian immigrants admitted from 1899 to 1910 was 
 48.9 per cent and amongr the Polish immigrants admitted 
 during the same period 35.4 per cent. 3 These averages are 
 derived from the records of over a million individuals of 
 both nationalities, whereas "the superiority of the Lithu- 
 anians over the Poles'* is deduced from 214 accidents that 
 occurred in one year in the mines of one company. 
 
 As far as the statistics of the Commission permit to judge 
 jf the antecedents of the Lithuanian and Polish anthra- 
 ite coal workers in their native countries, it appears that 
 aone of them had worked in mines before coming to the 
 United States; 96 per cent of the Lithuanians and 86 per 
 lent of the Poles from whom information was received had 
 been peasants (farmers and farm laborers) in their home 
 countries, the proportion of farmers and farmers' sons 
 being somewhat higher among the Poles than among the 
 Lithuanians, viz., 70 per cent and 60 per cent, respectively, 
 of the total number reported for each race. 4 To judge 
 by the historical experiences of the two races, there is 
 no warrant whatsoever for rating the mass of the Poles 
 below the mass of the Lithuanians. For centuries they 
 have been close neighbors. Since the organic union of 
 Poland and Lithuania in 1386, Polish civilization was 
 dominant in Lithuania. The ruling classes, the landed 
 nobility and the clergy were thoroughly Polonized. Since 
 
 1 Reports, vol. 16, p. 667 'Ibid., vol. 10, p. 772. 
 
 3 Ibid., vol. I, p. 99. Table II. *Ibid., vol. 16, p. 596, Table 9. 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 57 
 
 the policy of Russianization was inaugurated in Poland and 
 Lithuania fifty years ago, the Lithuanians have been at a 
 disadvantage compared with the Poles; the Lithuanian 
 language was barred from the public schools; they were 
 denied the right to have a press in their own language, while 
 the mass of the Lithuanian people do not understand the 
 Russian language. 
 
 The Immigration Commission has discovered no anthro- 
 pological evidence that would sustain the hypothesis of the 
 superiority of the Lithuanian race, unless the difference of 
 64 accidents be accepted as such evidence. Yet it appears 
 from the same accident statistics that the native Americans 
 also contributed more than their share of accident victims, 
 whereas the Irish exhibited an exceptionally low accident 
 rate. This variation, however, must not be construed to 
 show a superiority of the Irish over the native Americans, 
 because "for the accident report the State mine inspector 
 generally has to get the nationality from others, usually 
 friends of the victim or his boss," and the informa- 
 tion is often erroneous. "Probably the same source of 
 error accounts for some of the Polish accident excess." 1 
 Still, if not all of the 64 accidents then some of them are 
 deemed sufficient to place the Poles below the Lithuanians 
 on the sliding scale of foreign races. 
 
 It would seem as if the investigation of the Immigration 
 Commission proceeded upon the supposition that immigrant 
 races represented separate zoological species. Thus we 
 find the following under the head "diseases peculiar to 
 immigrant races": 
 
 The testimony of the physicians and hospital authorities is to the 
 effect that apparently (sic/) there are no diseases peculiar to any one 
 single race. The chief diseases among the aliens are the following: 
 (a) Rheumatism; (b) heart diseases; (c) typhoid fever; (d) pneumonia 
 this is one of the diseases most common to the foreign population, but 
 they seem no more subject to it than the natives. 9 
 
 Thus it has been officially established that disease 
 1 Reports, vol. 1 6, p. 667. *Ibid., vol. 8, p. 433- 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 " apparently " makes no distinction of race, color, or previous 
 condition of servitude, "the aliens" being subject, alike 
 with native-born and naturalized citizens, to rheumatism and 
 pneumonia. The habits of the new species are described in 
 the language of the naturalist. We learn, e. g., that among 
 the Bulgarians beef "is usualy cooked as a stew with veg- 
 etables and eaten with bread. They also consume all forms 
 of green vegetables in season. . . . The usual drinks are 
 coffee and beer. Many drink hot milk in the morning." ' 
 The adoption of the "race" idea as a basis for classification 
 has inevitably led to the splitting up of all statistical data 
 into minute groups unfit for any generalizations. The 
 Commission has nevertheless systematically reduced all 
 such data to percentages, which are used for comparison 
 among races. It is an elementary rule in statistics that 
 averages and percentages may be used for generalizations 
 only when derived from large numbers, the reason being 
 that where the number of observed cases is small personal 
 characteristics or casual circumstances may affect the 
 results. How deceptive percentage may be when derived 
 from insufficient numbers, is illustrated by the following 
 table compiled from the Commission's statistics, showing 
 the "per cent of foreign-born employees (in the clothing 
 factories investigated) who speak English, by sex, years in 
 the United States, and race." 3 
 
 TABLE i. 
 
 PER CENT WHO SPEAK ENGLISH, BY YEARS, IN THE UNITED STATES 
 
 
 Under 
 5 years 
 
 5 to 9 
 
 years 
 
 10 years 
 or over 
 
 Total 
 
 Male 
 Bohemian and Moravian 
 Polish 
 
 22.5 
 24.8 
 
 18.1 
 19.4 
 
 45-0 
 62.4 
 
 sf-5 
 63-0 
 
 75.0 
 83-2 
 
 88.0 
 89.4 
 
 56.0 
 51-1 
 
 54-8 
 49-9 
 
 Female 
 Bohemian and Moravian. . . . 
 Polish 
 
 1 Reports, vol. 9, p. 82. 
 
 3 Ibid., vol. II, p. 363, Table 95, 
 
Report of the Immigration Commission 59 
 
 The significance of the preceding table is in the fact that the 
 Bohemians and Moravians are classed by the Immigration 
 Restriction League among "desirable" immigrants, where- 
 as the Poles belong to the "undesirable aliens from Eastern 
 Europe." A comparison of the figures in the first three 
 columns shows, however, that in each group classified 
 according to length of residence in the United States the 
 Poles show a higher percentage of males, as well as females, 
 able to speak English, than the Bohemians. And yet when 
 the totals are compared for both nationalities, irrespective 
 of length of residence in the United States, it appears that 
 the Bohemians exhibit a larger percentage of persons of 
 either sex able to speak English, than the Poles. The 
 reason for this arithmetical aberration is disclosed only in 
 another part of the volume, where the number of persons 
 in each of the preceding groups is given. It appears that 
 about one-half of all Poles had resided in the United States 
 less than five years and accordingly exhibited a small per- 
 centage of persons able to speak English, whereas three 
 fourths of all males and two thirds of all females of 
 Bohemian nationality had resided in the United States 
 over five years and had had more time to learn English. 1 
 
 1 The following are the numbers relating to the two rationalities: 
 
 Male 
 Bohemian and 
 Moravian . . 
 Polish 
 
 Number 
 reporting 
 complete 
 data 
 
 Years in the United States 
 
 Under 5 
 
 5 top 
 
 I o or over 
 
 Num- 
 ber 
 
 Number 
 who speak 
 English 
 
 Num- 
 ber 
 
 Number 
 who speak 
 English 
 
 Num- 
 ber 
 
 Number 
 who speak 
 English 
 
 219 
 153 
 
 117 
 127 
 
 - 
 
 532 
 667 
 
 347 
 43i 
 
 129 
 3 02 
 
 127 
 216 
 
 29 
 
 75 
 
 23 
 
 42 
 
 III 
 181 
 
 87 
 73 
 
 50 
 
 "3 
 
 50 
 46 
 
 
 
 292 
 
 184 
 
 133 
 142 
 
 
 
 Female 
 Bohemian anc 
 Moravian. . 
 Polish 
 
 
 1 Reports, vol. 11, pp. 54<>. 54* Table 53< 
 
60 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The numbers reported permit of no conclusion beyond the 
 bare fact that the Bohemians are an older immigrant race 
 than the Poles, yet the total percentages tend to create 
 the wholly unjustified impression that the Poles are less 
 capable of " assimilation " than the Bohemians. 1 
 
 The defects of the plan and statistical method of the 
 Commission render the bulk of its report on Immigrants in 
 Industries valueless or misleading. 
 
 1 The reports of the Immigration Commission abound with such 
 comparative percentages. A few samples only can be quoted in these 
 pages. To judge by percentages, the migratory spirit reaches its extreme 
 height 60.0 per cent among the Greeks employed in the packing 
 industry after they have been in the United States over ten years. On 
 closer examination it appears, however, that there were five Greeks all 
 told who had been in the United States more than ten years, and of 
 their number three had visited abroad. (Reports, vol. 13, p. 151, 
 Table 105.) In another place the following comment is made: "The 
 employment of the wife or keeping boarders or lodgers is less frequent 
 among the native-born of foreign father. " This conclusion is derived 
 from the reports on just four families whose heads are native-born ol 
 foreign father. (Ibid., voL 1 1 , p. 3 1 1 .) 
 
CHAPTER III 
 
 OLD AND NEW IMMIGRATION 
 
 IT has come to be accepted as an unquestionable truth 
 so often has it been repeated that the type of the old 
 immigrant was superior to the recent immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe : 
 
 Fifty, even thirty years ago, [said Gen. F. A. Walker in 1896], there 
 was a rightful presumption regarding the average immigrant, that he 
 was among the most enterprising, thrifty, alert, adventurous, and 
 courageous of the community from which he came. It required no 
 small energy, prudence, forethought, and pains to conduct the inquiries 
 relating to his migration, to accumulate the necessary means, and to 
 find his way across the Atlantic. x 
 
 The immigrants of those happy days 
 
 did not come because they were assisted by others, they did not come 
 because some one paid their passage to get them out of the old coun- 
 try, but they came because they wanted to be free. . . . They came 
 not at the behest of the agents of the steamship lines or the agent 
 of the large American industries, sent over to buy labor as by auction, 
 in the market. ... No; they came at their own behest, and did not 
 all settle down in the centers of American life to congest it, but struck 
 out into the prairies and forest to build homes for themselves and 
 families. 8 
 
 "Those were skilled artisans or progressive farmers of the 
 thrifty, self-reliant type." 3 
 
 1 Francis A. Walker: Discussions in Economics and Statistics, p. 446. 
 
 3 Statement of Rev. M. D. Lichliter, chaplain of the Junior Order 
 American Mechanics before the House Committee on Immigration an 
 Naturalization, Sixty first Congress. Hearings, p. 49 * 
 
 3 Frank Tracy Carlton: The History and Problems of Organized 
 Labor, p. 328. 
 
 61 
 
62 Immigration and Labor 
 
 It is the old story of the Golden Age in a modern version. 
 The cold facts of history, however, do not bear out this 
 popular myth. 
 
 The great majority of immigrants to this country were so poor that 
 they could not buy their passage, and in order to meet the obligations 
 incurred by them for passage money and other advances, they were sold, 
 after their arrival, into temporary servitude. . . . The prepayment of 
 the passage was the exception, and its subsequent discharge by compul- 
 sory labor the rule. 1 The ship owners and ship merchants derived 
 enormous profits from the sale of bodies of immigrants, as they charged 
 very high rates for the passage, to which they added a heavy percentage 
 often more than a hundred per cent for their risks. But the immi- 
 grants suffered bitterly from this traffic in human flesh. Old people, 
 widows, and cripples would not sell well, while healthy parents with 
 healthy children and young people of both sexes always found a ready 
 market. If the parents were too old to work, their children had to 
 serve so much longer to make up the difference. When one or both 
 parents died on the voyage, their children had to serve for them. The 
 expenses of the whole family were summed up and charged upon the 
 survivor or survivors. Adults had to serve from three to six years; 
 children from ten to fifteen years, till they became of age; smaller 
 children were, without charge, surrendered to masters, who had to 
 raise and board them. As all servants signed indentures, they were 
 called ' ' indentured servants. " Whenever a vessel arrived at Philadel- 
 phia or New York its passengers were offered at public sale. The ship 
 was the market-place, and the servants were struck off to the highest 
 bidder. The country people either came themselves or sent agents or 
 friends to procure what they wanted, be it a girl, or a "likely boy, or 
 an old housekeeper, or a whole family. . . . Parents sold their children 
 in order to remain free themselves. When a young man or girl had an 
 opportunity to get married they had to pay their master five or six 
 pounds for each year they had to serve. Yet a steerage passage never 
 cost more than ten pounds. ... If the master did not want to keep his 
 servant he could sell him for the unexpired time of his term of servitude. a 
 
 "The newspapers of the time regularly contain advertise- 
 
 1 Prof. Commons estimates that probably one half of all the immigrants 
 of the colonial period landed as indentured servants. A. M. Simons: 
 Social Forces in American History, p. 19. 
 
 a From a paper read before the American Social Science Association 
 in New York City, in 1869, by State Commissioner of Immigration, 
 Friedrich Kapp. X VI. Annual Report of the New York Bureau of Labor 
 Statistics, pp. 964-965. 
 
Old and New Immigration 63 
 
 ments of the arrival of ships with 'indentured servants' 
 to be sold. In case no buyers came to the ship the pas- 
 sengers were sold to agents, who chained them together 
 and peddled them through the towns and villages." 1 
 * So great then was the poverty of the early immigrants 
 that for the sum of ten pounds they were willing to sell 
 themselves into peonage. The last sales of immigrants 
 are reported in 1819 in Philadelphia. 2 
 
 Nearly a century ago, the managers of the Society for 
 the Prevention of Pauperism in the City of New York 
 spoke of the immigrants "in the language of astonishment 
 and apprehension": 
 
 Through this inlet pauperism threatens us with the most overwhelm- 
 ing consequences. . . . The present state of Europe contributes in a 
 thousand ways to foster unceasing immigration to the United States. 
 . . An almost innumerable population beyond the ocean is out of 
 employment. . . . This country is the resort of vast numbers of these 
 needy and wretched beings. . . . They are frequently found destitute 
 in our streets, they seek employment at our doors; they are found in 
 our almshouses and in our hospitals; they are found at the bar of our 
 criminal tribunals, in our bridewell, our penitentiary, and our State 
 prison, and we lament to say that they are too often led by want, by 
 vice, and by habit to form a phalanx of plunder and depredations, 
 rendering our city more liable to increase of crimes and our houses of 
 correction more crowded with convicts and felons. 3 
 
 Eighteen years later the Mayor of New York City in a 
 communication to the City Council complained that the 
 streets were "filled with wandering crowds" of immigrants 
 "clustering in our city, unacquainted with our climate, 
 without employment, without friends, not speaking our 
 language, and without any dependence for food, or raiment, 
 or fireside, certain of nothing but hardship and a grave." 4 
 
 1 Simons, loc. cit., p. 19. a Kapp, loc. cit., p. 965. 
 
 3 Second Annual Report of the Managers of the Society for the Pre- 
 vention of Pauperism in the City of New York, 1819. Quoted from 
 the Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 449- 
 
 4 H. R., 61 st Congress. Hearings before Committee on Immigration, 
 
 P- 369. 
 
64 Immigration and Labor 
 
 This was the period when, according to Gen. F. A. 
 Walker, the average immigrant was "enterprising, thrifty, 
 ,'tlert, adventurous, and courageous." A contemporary 
 writer anticipated General Walker's parallel between the 
 old and the new immigration in almost identical language.' 1 
 
 A generation later it is again reported that "the poor and 
 She productive classes of Europe, by hundreds of thousands, 
 have been, and are now coming to our shores, with fixed 
 habits and modes of life. These now constitute, mainly, 
 the army of our unskilled laborers, are ignorant and de- 
 graded, pitifully so." 2 
 
 Regarding the standard of living of the Irish peasantry 
 at the beginning of the Irish exodus to America, when, 
 according to General Walker's "rightful presumption," 
 the average immigrant was thrifty and had accumulated 
 the necessary means to pay his way, we have the following 
 description from the same authority: 
 
 The conditions under which they had been born and brought up 
 were generally of the most squalid and degrading character. Their 
 wretched hovels, thatched with rotting straw, scantily furnished with 
 light, hardly ventilated at all, frequently with no floor but the clay 
 on which they were built, were crowded beyond the bounds of comfort, 
 health, or, as it would seem to us, of simple social decency; their beds 
 were heaps of straw or rags; their food consisted mainly of buttermilk 
 and potatoes, often of the worst, and commonly inadequate in amount ; 
 their clothing was scanty and shabby. * 
 
 1 " Then our accessions of immigration were real accessions of strength 
 from the ranks of the learned and the good, from enlightened mechanic 
 and artisan and intelligent husbandman. Now, immigration is the 
 accession of weakness, from the ignorant and vicious, or the priest- 
 ridden slaves of Ireland and Germany, or the outcast tenants of the 
 poorhouses and prisons of Europe." From a paper entitled "Imminent 
 Dangers to the Institutions of the United States through Foreign 
 Immigration," etc., by S. F. B. Morse, 1835. H. R. Sixty-first Con- 
 gress. Hearings before the Committee on Immigration, p. 327. 
 
 2 Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor, 1869-1870, 
 p. 88. 
 
 y Walker, loc. cit., p. 451. The following is quoted elsewhere by the 
 game author from the report of Earl Devon's Commission on Irish 
 Poverty in the 40*3: " In many districts, their daily food is the potato; 
 
Old and New Immigration 65 
 
 Congestion was a common evil in those days, as it is 
 to-day, and the reason for it was sought in the fact that the 
 Irish immigrant, born in a cabin or a garret, had been used 
 to crowding at home. 1 The New York Weekly Tribune 
 of May 2, 1846, discussing a strike of Irish laborers in 
 Brooklyn, said that their earnings were hardly sufficient 
 to pay the rent of a decent tenement, so "they were allowed 
 to build miserable shanties on ground allotted them by 
 the contractors on the plot occupied by them in performing 
 the work." 2 A quarter of a century later the dwellings 
 of the Irish immigrants in Boston were officially charac- 
 terized as "sickening kennels. " 3 Says Dr. Kate H. Claghorn, 
 comparing the old immigration with the new: "No account 
 of filth in daily surroundings among 4Htai and 
 can outmatch the pictures drawn by observers of the habits 
 of immigrant Irish and even Germans." 4 
 
 The living conditions in an Irish district in 1864 were 
 thus described by a city inspector: 
 
 The tenants seem to wholly disregard personal cleanliness, if not the 
 very first principles of decency, their general appearance and actions 
 corresponding with their wretched abodes. This indifference to per- 
 sonal and domiciliary cleanliness is doubtless acquired from a long 
 
 their only beverage water; their cabins are seldom a protection against 
 the weather; a bed or a blanket is a rare luxury; and, in nearly all, their 
 pig and manure heap constitute their only property./" Francis A. Walker: t 
 Political Economy, pp. 313-314. "In the 40*8, at the time of the potato 
 famine in Ireland, many of the thousands who came to this country 
 were in serious danger of absolute starvation if they remained at home. 
 Practically none of our immigrants of the present day are in such a con- 
 dition." Jenks and Lauck: The Immigration Problem, p. 12. 
 
 1 A contemporary writer had "seen in Ireland a horse, two cows, two 
 goats, grandmother, father and mother, brother and sisters, an infant 
 in a cradle, all in one apartment. "Report of the Industrial Commission, 
 vol. xv., p. 459. 
 
 2 Documentary History of American Industrial Society, vol. viii., pp. 
 225-226. 
 
 3 Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor, 1869-70, 
 p. 88. 
 
 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 491. 
 
66 Immigration and Labor 
 
 familiarity with the loathsome surroundings, wholly at variance with 
 all moral or social improvements. 1 
 
 A gloomy picture of the moral effects of bad housing 
 conditions in the foreign sections of New York City in 1878, 
 when the immigrants were only Irish and Germans, was 
 drawn in a report of the Association for the Improvement 
 of the Condition of the Poor: 
 
 In many quarters of the city family life and the feeling of home are 
 almost unknown; people live in great caravansaries, which are hot and 
 stifling in summer, disagreeable in winter, and where children associate 
 together in the worst way. In many rooms privacy and purity are 
 unattainable, and young girls grow up accustomed to immodesty from 
 ^flipAM^ y ea] )M4MN herd together in gangs, and learn the 
 practices of crime and vice' before they are out of childhood. Even 
 the laborers' families who occupy separate rooms in these buildings 
 have no sense of home. 3 
 
 Dr. Griscom, as early as 1842, had called attention to the "depraved 
 effects which such modes of life exert upon the moral feelings and 
 habits"; and the city inspector in 1851 remarks that " these over- 
 populated houses are generally, if not always, seminaries of filthiness, 
 indecency, and lawlessness."* 
 
 Dr. Claghorn concludes her review of the housing con- 
 ditions of the former generations of immigrants with the 
 following remarks: ' 
 
 The newer immigrants arrive here at no lower social level, to say the 
 least, than did their predecessors. Their habits of life, their general 
 morality and intelligence can not be called decidedly inferior. . . . The 
 Italian ragpicker was astonishingly like his German predecessor, and 
 the Italian laborer is of quite as high a type as the Irish laborer of a 
 generation ago. In some cases the newer immigrants have brought 
 about positive improvements in the quarters they have entered. Whole 
 blocks have been transferred from nests of pauperism and vice into 
 quiet industrial neighborhoods by the incoming of Italians and Hebrews. 
 
 Throughout the nineteenth century relief against city 
 
 Report of the Industrial Commission, p. 456. a Ibid., p. 459. 
 * Loc. cit.. p. 458. * Loc. cit. t p. 491. 
 
Old and New Immigration 
 
 67 
 
 poverty was sought in directing the current of immigration to 
 the farm. As early as 1 8 1 7, ' * the same anxiety was felt that 
 is felt to-day to get the immigrant out of the 'crowded' 
 cities into the country beyond." 1 In 1819, the managers 
 of the Society for the Prevention of Pauperism of the City 
 of New York favored the plan of establishing "communica- 
 tion . . . with our great farmers and landholders in the in- 
 terior" with a view to provide "ways and means ... for 
 the transportation of able-bodied foreigners into the in- 
 terior," where labor could be provided for them "upon the 
 soiL" 2 Forty years later the Association for the Improve- 
 ment of the Condition of the Poor complained of the Irish 
 immigrants that "they had an utter distaste for felling 
 forests and turning up the prairies fgf ' Lhemselv^^'JMifey 
 preferred to stay where another race would furnish them 
 with food, clothing, and labor, and hence were mostly found 
 loitering on the lines of the public works, in villages, and in 
 the worst portions of the large cities where they competed 
 ^vith negroes ... for the most degrading employments."^ 
 * The old immigrants, like those of the present generation, 
 were mostly unskilled laborers and farm hands, as will 
 appear from an analysis of Table 2 next following. 4 
 
 TABLE 2. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF IMMIGRANTS BY OCCUPATIONS: 
 I86I-I9IO. 
 
 Occupation 
 
 1861- 
 
 1870 
 
 1871- 
 1880 
 
 1881- 
 1890 
 
 1891- 
 
 1900 
 
 1901- 
 1910 
 
 Professional. 
 
 0.8 
 
 1.4 
 
 I.I 
 
 0.9 
 
 1-5 
 
 Skilled. 
 
 24.0 
 
 23.1 
 
 20.4 
 
 20.1 
 
 20.2 
 
 
 17.6 
 
 18.2 
 
 14.0 
 
 II- 4 
 
 24-3 
 
 Unskilled laborers . . . 
 
 4.2.4 
 
 41.9 
 
 50.2 
 
 47.0 
 
 34-8 
 
 Servants 
 
 7.2 
 
 7-7 
 
 9-4 
 
 i5-i 
 
 14.1 
 
 All other occupations 
 
 8.0 
 
 7-7 
 
 9-4 
 
 5-5 
 
 5-i 
 
 Total 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, p. 449 3 Loc - cit "> P* 4 62 - 
 
 tReportofthe A. I. C. P., 1860, p. 50- Quoted from Report of the 
 
 Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 462. 
 
 <For annual averages and sources of information see Appendix, 
 
 Table I. 
 
68 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The sharp fluctuations of the percentages of agricultural 
 workers and common laborers indicate that the distinction 
 between farm laborers and other laborers was probably not 
 very accurately drawn in our immigration statistics. For 
 the period 1901-1910 it is possible to subdivide all persons 
 engaged in agricultural pursuits into farmers and farm 
 laborers, the former constituting i .6 per cent and the latter 
 23.0 per cent of all immigrant breadwinners. 
 
 Allowing the same percentage for the decade next preced- 
 ing, with a rising tide of immigration from Eastern and 
 Southern Europe, and estimating the maximum proportion 
 of farmers in the "old immigration" at one half of all in- 
 coming agricultural workers, 1 we arrive at the following 
 comparative ratios for unskilled laborers and farm help 
 combined. 
 
 TABLE 3 
 
 RATIO OF LABORERS TO IMMIGRANT BREADWINNERS. 
 
 Period Per cent . 
 
 1861-1870 51.2 
 
 I87I-I880 51.0 
 
 1881-1890 57.2 
 
 1891-1900 57.0 
 
 1901-1910 57.9 
 
 The ratio of unskilled laborers and farm hands to the 
 total number of breadwinners exhibits but little change 
 during the whole fifty-year period. For the half-century 
 beginning in 1820, the proportion of unskilled laborers, 
 exclusive of those classified under agricultural pursuits, 
 has been computed as 46.6 per cent, 2 i. e., about the same as 
 for the later period. 
 
 1 This is vastly more than is claimed for the "old immigration" by 
 Professors Jenks and Lauck in their unofficial summary of the reports 
 of the Immigration Commission, wherein they say that "the percentage 
 of farmers as distinguished from farm laborers has always been very 
 small, so small as not to be an appreciable factor in determining our 
 civilization." Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t p. 31. 
 
 Political Science Quarterly, March, 1904; Roland P. Falkner: Some 
 Aspects of the Immigration Problem, p. 49. 
 
Old and New Immigration 69 
 
 The percentage of skilled mechanics has varied but little 
 for the last fifty years, and has at no time reached one 
 quarter of all immigrant breadwinners. If this percentage 
 is added to the estimated maximum ratio of farmers, it 
 will be found that the aggregate of "skilled artisans and 
 progressive farmers of the thrifty, self-reliant type" could 
 in the good old days not have been as high as one third of 
 the total immigration. 
 
 Still it is broadly asserted that the "new immigration" 
 is drawn from the "poorest and least desirable" elements of 
 the population of Italy, Austria, and Russia. "Measured 
 either by intellectual, social, economic or material standards, 
 the average immigrant of any particular class from these 
 countries is far below the best of his countrymen who*remain 
 behind, and probably also below the average." 1 
 
 No comparative study of the immigrants and their coun- 
 trymen who remain at home is cited in support of this 
 view. It still rests on the purely deductive argument, first 
 advanced by Mayo-Smith twenty-four years ago, that, as 
 the result of the increase of transportation facilities and the 
 reduction of the cost of passage, "it is more and more the 
 lower classes that are coming." In corroboration of this 
 argument he cited the fact that the Irish and German immi- 
 grants of his day were coming from the poorer sections of 
 their countries. 2 It is obvious, however, that the inhabi- 
 tants of those sections were not all on the same economic 
 level. Lack of opportunities in a poor country will drive 
 people of some means to seek better luck abroad, while 
 lack of funds will keep the poorest at home. Be that as 
 it may, since the time of Mayo-Smith the steerage rates 
 have been doubled. The increase in the cost of transpor- 
 
 1 William Williams: New Immigration, p. 286. Report of the 
 Conference of Charities and Corrections, 1906. See also Prescott F. Hall : 
 Selection of Immigration, Annals of American Academy of Political and 
 Social Science, July, 1904, p. 174; Robert Hunter: Poverty, p. 270. 
 
 2 Richmond Mayo-Smith : " Control of Immigration," Political Science 
 Quarterly, 1888, pp. 62, 69, 70, and 71. 
 
70 Immigration and Labor 
 
 tation has been tantamount to a head tax of from $18 to 
 $27* and should have raised the standard of the "new im- 
 migration," as compared with the immigrants of the 70*5 
 and the early 8o's. j 
 
 Leaving aside, however, all speculative considerations, 
 we have a purely objective standard of comparison, viz., 
 the ratio of literacy. It is generally recognized that "prob- 
 ably the most apparent cause of illiteracy in Europe, as 
 elsewhere, is poverty. The economic status of a people has 
 a very decided effect upon the literacy rate. . . . Another 
 phase of the economic factor is the need of children's 
 service at home." 2 
 
 While the statistics of illiteracy among immigrants to the 
 United States are not compiled on a uniform basis with 
 foreign statistics of illiteracy, still for a few countries and 
 nationalities the data are fairly comparable. An exami- 
 nation of the figures presented in Table 4 shows that as a 
 rule the mtio of illiteracy among the immigrants is con- 
 siderably lower than among their countrymen at home. 3 
 Thesj statistics prove that measured by intellectual standards 
 the average immigrant is above the average of his countrymen 
 who remain behind. Illiteracy being the effect of poverty 
 (by hypothesis), one cannot escape the conclusion that, 
 measured by economic standards, the immigrant is likewise 
 above the average of his native country. " 
 
 1 " During the later seventies and early eighties the steerage passenger 
 rate fluctuated from as low as $12 up as high as $25, but averaged about 
 $i7or$i8. . . . In the later eighties and early nineties . . . most of 
 the foreign steamship companies there were no native companies 
 gradually increased the steerage rates to about $38 or $39. . . . (The 
 rates charged now) vary from about $36 to $38 and $39, depending 
 upon the port, vessel, and so forth. Thirty-seven dollars and fifty 
 cents is commonly quoted as the average." Hearings before Committee 
 on Immigration and Naturalization, H. R-. 6ist Congress: Statement of 
 James H. Patten, pp. 31-32. 
 
 2 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, pp. 34-35. 
 
 * See Note on the Statistics of Italian Illiteracy, at end of chapter. 
 
Old and New Immigration 71 
 
 TABLE 4. 
 
 PER CENT OF ILLITERACY AMONG THE POPULATION OF RUSSIA, BULGARIA, 
 
 SERVIA AND GREECE, AND AMONG THE IMMIGRANTS FROM 
 
 THE SAME COUNTRIES. 1 
 
 Nationality, 
 
 Population 
 
 Immigrants 14 years of age and 
 over, year ended June 30 
 
 year of enumeration, 
 and age group 
 
 
 1908 
 
 1890-1910 
 
 
 Male 
 
 Female 
 
 Male 
 
 Female 
 
 Both sexes. 
 
 Russia, 1897: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Russians: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 10 to 19 years 
 20 years and 
 over 
 
 51.3 
 62.6 
 
 8 3 .6 f 
 89.7 ) 
 
 4O.I 
 
 50.8 
 
 38.4 
 
 Hebrews 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 i o to 19 years 
 20 years and 
 
 41-3 
 
 58.0 ) 
 
 21.9 
 
 40.4 
 
 26.0 8 
 
 over 
 
 32.6 
 
 66.2 ) 
 
 
 
 
 Bulgaria, ipoo: 
 14 years and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 over 
 
 57-3 
 
 89.4^ 
 
 
 
 
 Servia, IQOO: 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 ii to 1 5 years 
 
 55-7 
 
 89.6 [ 
 
 35-0 
 
 50.2 
 
 41.7 
 
 1 6 to 20 years 
 
 58.8 
 
 90.9 
 
 
 
 
 21 years and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 over 
 
 70.2 
 
 94.4 J 
 
 
 
 
 Greece, 1907: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 4 years and 
 
 42.6 
 
 82.2 
 
 26.9 
 
 57-5 
 
 
 over 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i , p. 99. Report of the 
 Commission of Immigration of the State of New York, ipop, pp. 170 and 
 171. Premier Re"censement Ge"ne"ral de la Population de I'Empire de 
 Russie, 1897. Releve" G<ne"ral, Part 2, pp. 97 and 134. Bulgarie, Re"- 
 censement de la population, 1900, vol. i., p. 125. Annuaire Statistique 
 du Royaume de Serbie pour 1900, vol. v., pp. 75-80. Grece, Re"cense- 
 ment de la population, 1907, vol. i, pp. 156-157. 
 
 2 This percentage represents the ratio of illiteracy among the Hebrews 
 of all countries, but the bulk of Hebrew immigration comes from Russia. 
 The population statistics of Austria classify Hebrews as Poles, Germans, 
 etc., according to mother tongue. The ratio of illiteracy among the 
 
72 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The Immigration Commission on its trip to Europe 
 sought the opinions of experts respecting the character of 
 emigration to the United States. The conclusions reached 
 by the Commission have none of the pessimistic sound 
 typical of restrictionist literature. Says the Commission: 
 
 The present movement is not recruited in the main from the lowest 
 economic and social strata of the population. . . . Neither do the 
 average or typical emigrants of to-day represent the lowest in the eco- 
 nomic and social scale even among the classes from which they come, a 
 circumstance attributable to both natural and artificial causes. In the 
 first place, emigrating to a strange and distant country, although less of 
 an undertaking than formerly, is still a serious and relatively difficult 
 matter, requiring a degree of courage and resourcefulness not possessed 
 by weaklings of any class. This natural law in the main regulated the 
 earlier European emigration to the United States, and under its in- 
 fluence the present emigration, whether or not desirable as a whole, 
 nevertheless represents the stronger and better element of the particular 
 class from which it is drawn. x 
 
 Roumanian Hebrews 15 years of age and over, according to the census 
 of 1889, was 55.6 per cent. ("Sans protection," meaning mostly 
 Hebrews.) Rsultats de*finitifs du de*nombrement de la population de 
 Roumanie, 1899, p. Ixii. 
 
 1 Reports, vol. 4 (in press). From the opinions of Americans who 
 had long resided in Italy and of leading Italians, which are quoted in the 
 Commission's report, a few are selected here by way of illustration. 
 
 Rev. N. W. Clark, an American, in charge of the educational work 
 of the Methodist Church of Italy, said: "The class of emigrants who go 
 to the United States are unquestionably the more enterprising, the better 
 element; only those would be able to go who have the money to get 
 tickets; many are too poor to go. " 
 
 In a report to the Department of State, the American Consul at 
 Palermo quotes the country correspondents of a Sicilian news- 
 paper, concerning the local estimate of the character of emigration 
 from that island. "As these accounts says he were in no way 
 prepared for the foreign eye, or for any official or political purpose, 
 but only by way of a routine chronicle of the happenings of life in the 
 minor communities, they are spontaneous and unbiased and have an 
 authority that can hardly be impeached:*' One of the correspondents 
 says of the emigrants that they are not "driven out by dire want and 
 necessity; they are lured rather by the desire to better themselves in 
 the world and make a possible fortune. . . . Many are of a class 
 
Old and New Immigration 73 
 
 The social prejudice against the immigrant which it is 
 sought to justify by his alleged inferiority, antedates the 
 influx of the " undesirable aliens from Eastern and Southern 
 Europe." Suffice it to recall the agitation of the Know- 
 Nothing days, with its rioting and outbreaks of mob vio- 
 lence against the Irish, the desecration of their churches, 
 the petty persecution of Irish children in the public schools, 
 the denunciation of the Germans,. the mobbing of German 
 newspapers and Turner halls. * 
 
 Probably the most important element in this antipathy was the pure 
 contempt which men usually feel for those whose standards of life seem 
 inferior. This feeling was felt towards all immigrants of the poorer 
 class, irrespective of their race. To the mind of the average American 
 the typical immigrant was a being uncleanly in habits, uncouth in 
 speech, lax in the moralities, ignorant in mind, and unskilled in labor. 
 . . . The immigrant bore a stamp of social inequality. 3 
 
 The manifestations of this social prejudice in the indus- 
 trial field seventy years ago were much the same as to-day. 
 
 About the year 1836 to 1840, very material changes took place among 
 . . . the general laboring help in all departments of industry. The 
 profuse immigrations from Ireland. . . crowded into all the fields of 
 labqr, and crowded out the former occupants. Under the prejudice of 
 nationality . . . the American element, the daughters of independent 
 farmers, educated in our common schools . . . retired from mill and 
 factory, and all the older establishments, and can no longer be found 
 therein. Their places were taken up in the old, and all the new were 
 filled by the new immigrants, s 
 
 possessing some little property. " Another correspondent speaks of the 
 emigrants as "the enterprising and robust youth . . . confiding in their 
 strength." According to him, "this emigration . . . comprises even 
 people of fairly easy circumstances. " 
 
 1 H. J. Desmond: The Know-Nothing Party, pp. 7-105. ^^ Dow 
 Scisco: Political Nativism in New York State, pp. 19, 248-249. Herr- 
 mann Von Hoist: Constitutional History of the United States, vol. v., pp. 
 188-190. James Schouler: History of the United States, vol. v., pp. 
 305-306. 
 
 a Scisco, loc. cit., p. 19. 
 
 3 First Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor, 1870, 
 p. 91. 
 
\ 
 74 Immigration and Labor 
 
 By a strange inconsistency those who object to the coming 
 of the immigrant as strongly object to his going. Why the 
 * ' bird^ of passage * * should have been the subject of popular 
 censure is from an economic point of view inconceivable. 
 So long as there are variations in business activity from year 
 to year and from season to season, which result in unem- 
 ployment, the American wage-earners should be the last to 
 object if a class of wage-earners choose to leave the country 
 temporarily while there is no demand for their services, 
 thereby relieving competition for jobs in its acutest shape. 
 From the point of view of the present immigration policy 
 as well, the departure of the "bird of passage" ought to be 
 approved as the best assurance that he would not "become 
 a public charge. " Still if an immigrant who comes to this 
 country when there is work to be done and leaves when he 
 is not wanted is to be regarded as an "undesirable alien," 
 it is of interest to know how the "new immigration" com- 
 pares in this respect with the "old immigration." "The 
 one conclusion to be drawn from the record of departuf es 
 from the United States," says the Immigration Commis- 
 sion, "is that as a whole the races or peoples composing 
 the old immigration are essentially permanent settlers, and 
 that a large proportion of the newer immigrants are simply 
 transients." 1 
 
 "The one conclusion" is, however, not the only one, for 
 in another volume the Commission takes a more hopeful 
 view, to wit: 
 
 It is inaccurate to speak of the immigrant population as being only 
 temporarily in this country. It is true, no doubt, that most of the 
 recent immigrants hope at first to return some day to their native land, 
 but the whole history of immigration goes to show that with the pass- 
 ing years and the growth of the inevitable ties, whether domestic, 
 financial, or political, binding the immigrant to his new abode, these 
 hopes decline and finally disappear. a 
 
 Inasmuch as the conclusions of the Commission contradict 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, p. 40. 
 
 2 Ibid., vol. 8, p. 657. 
 
Old and New Immigration 
 
 75 
 
 each other, we must go back to the facts from which they 
 are drawn. The Immigration Commission in its investi- 
 gation paid considerable attention to this question. The 
 foreign-born workmen in iron and steel mills are classed by 
 popular belief among the most "undesirable" elements of 
 the "new immigration." The comparative frequency 
 among them of the objectionable character addicted to the 
 habit of visiting his old home and parents, may accordingly 
 be accepted as typical of the races of the "new immigra- 
 tion." The Commission's data, presented in Table 5, show 
 that the English-speaking races harbor among them a higher 
 proportion of these offenders than all Eastern and Southern 
 European races, except the North Italians and the Slovaks. 
 The former, however, do not differ in this respect from the 
 Scotch, while the Slovaks exceed the Swedes by a fraction of 
 i per cent. 
 
 TABLE 5. 
 
 VISITS ABROAD MADE BY FOREIGN-BORN EMPLOYEES IN IRON AND STEEL 
 MILLS, BY RACES. 1 
 
 Northern and Western European Races. 
 
 Southern and Eastern European Races. 
 
 Nationality. 
 
 Per cent. 
 
 Nationality. 
 
 Per cent. 
 
 Canadian 46.1 
 
 Scotch 27.6 
 
 Welsh. 24.7 
 
 English 24.0 
 
 Swedish 21.0 
 
 Italian, North 27.6 
 
 Slovak 21.4 
 
 Italian, South 20.7 
 
 Magyar 20.3 
 
 Roumanian I5- 1 
 
 Croatian 14.3 
 
 Slovenian 13-9 
 
 Servian 12.2 
 
 Russian 10.2 
 
 Greek 8.8 
 
 Bohemian and Moravian 8.5 
 
 Poli^ &&. 
 
 Lithuanian 6.2 
 
 Even the vexed problem of "assimilation" appears to be 
 as old as immigration itself. Benjamin Franklin, in a 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, p. 152, Table no. 
 
76 Immigration and Labor 
 
 personal letter dated Philadelphia, May 9, 1753, charac- 
 terized the Germans of Pennsylvania in the following terms : 
 
 Those who come hither are generally the most stupid of their own 
 nation, and as ignorance is often attended with great credulity, when 
 knavery would mislead it ... it is almost impossible to remove any 
 prejudice they may entertain. . . . Not being used to liberty they 
 know not how to make modest use of it. ... I remember when they 
 modestly declined intermeddling with our elections; but now they come 
 in droves and carry all before them, except in one or two counties. 
 
 Few of their children know English. They import only books from 
 Germany, and of the six printing houses in the Province, two are entirely 
 German, two half German, half English, and but two are entirely Eng- 
 lish. They have one German newspaper and one half German. Ad- 
 vertisements intended to be general are now printed in Dutch and 
 English. The signs in our streets (Philadelphia) have inscriptions in 
 both languages, and some places only in German. They begin, of late, 
 to make all their bonds and other legal instruments in their own language, 
 which (though I think it ought not to be) are allowed in our courts, 
 where the German business so increases, that there is continued need of 
 interpreters, and I suppose in a few years they will also be necessary 
 in the Assembly, to tell one half of our legislators what the other half 
 says. In short, unless the stream of importation could be turned from 
 this to other colonies, as you very judiciously propose, they will soon 
 outnumber us, that all the advantages we will have will in my opinion, 
 be not able to preserve our language, and even our government will 
 become precarious. 1 
 
 Franklin's apprehensions concerning the Legislature of 
 Pennsylvania were all but justified at the convention of the 
 State of Pennsylvania held at Philadelphia from July 15 to 
 September 28, 1776, whose minutes were ordered published 
 weekly in English and German. 2 This practice was still 
 continued as late as I79O. 3 
 
 The conditions in Pennsylvania were by no means ex- 
 ceptional. Says Prof. McMaster of the same period: 
 
 1 Frank Ried Diffenderffer: The German Immigration into Pennsyl- 
 vania, 1700 to 1775, Part II, pp. 110-113^ 
 
 a Pennsylvania House Journal, vol. i, p. 57, Friday, July 26, 1776, 
 
 P.M. 
 
 * Journal of the Senate of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania, vol 
 i, 1790-1791, p. 22, Thursday, December 16, 1790. 
 
Old and New Immigration 77 
 
 Diverse as the inhabitants of the States . . . were in occupations 
 they were not less diverse in opinions, in customs, and habits. . . ! 
 Differences of race, differences of nationality, of religious opinions, of 
 manners, of tastes, even of speech, were still distinctly marked. 
 In New York the Dutch element prevailed and the language of Holland 
 was very generally spoken. 1 
 
 With the great influx of Irish and German immigrants 
 in the middle of the nineteenth century, distinct colonies of 
 those nationalities grew up in the larger cities. 
 
 So large are the aggregations of different foreign nationalities [says 
 a report of that day] that they no longer conform to our habits, opinions, 
 and manners, but, on the contrary, create for themselves distinct com- 
 munities, almost as impervious to American sentiments and influences 
 as are the inhabitants of Dublin or Hamburg. . . . They have their 
 own theaters, recreations, amusements, military and national organiza- 
 tions; to a great extent their own schools, churches, and trade unions; 
 their own newspapers and periodical literature. 8 
 
 The Irish were accused of " clannishness," 3 like the "immi- 
 grants from Eastern and Southern Europe" in our day, 
 although "to a large extent this going apart of the Irish was 
 but natural in view of the contemptuous manner in which 
 the 'nativist* Americans treated them." 4 It took three 
 generations to raise "the Celts and the Teutons" to a place 
 among the "more desirable immigrants from Northern 
 and Western Europe." 
 
 Have the new immigrants given evidence of an assimi- 
 lability inferior to that exhibited by the Germans? Some 
 evidence on this subject, collected by the Immigration 
 Commission, is given in Table 6 next below, relating to the 
 families of employees in the slaughtering and packing houses 
 of Kansas City: 
 
 ' John Bach McMaster: History of the People of the United States, 
 vol. i., pp. lo-n. s 
 
 3 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 455. 
 3 Scisco, loc. cit., p. 19. -. ' '* Desmond, loc. cit. t p. 9. 
 
78 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 6. 
 
 PER CENT OF POLISH AND GERMAN EMPLOYEES OF PACKING HOUSES IN 
 
 KANSAS CITY AND THEIR FOREIGN-BORN CHILDREN SIX YEARS 
 
 OF AGE OR OVER WHO SPEAK ENGLISH, BY YEARS IN 
 
 THE UNITED STATES. 1 
 
 Years in the United States Polish German 
 
 Under 5 26.1 20.0 
 
 5 to 9 73.2 70.0 ' . 
 
 10 or over 100.0 95-8 . 
 
 It can be seen from this table that the Polish workmen 
 and their children born abroad number among them a 
 larger percentage of English-speaking persons than the 
 Germans who have lived in the United States the same 
 length of time. This example need not be the general 
 rule, but it shows that the general classification of the 
 Germans as "English-speaking" and of the Poles as non- 
 English-speaking is purely a matter of prejudice. 
 * It is obviously not the character of the new immigration 
 that is the real cause of the popular feeling. The opposition 
 of organized labor, the main social force behind the present 
 agitation for restriction, originated at a time when the 
 numbers of immigrants from Eastern and Southern Europe 
 were too small to attract attention. Resolutions in opposi- 
 tion to immigration were adopted by the National Labor 
 Union as early as i868. 2 The report of the president to 
 the convention of the Cigarmakers' Union held in 1879 
 discussed immigration among "the evils which affect the 
 trade. 7 ' 3 
 
 The report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics 
 for 1885, in a summary of the testimony taken on the sub- 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 13, Table 256, p. 329. 
 a Documentary History of American Industrial Society, vol. ix., pp. 221- 
 
 222. 
 
 s Cigarmakers' Official Journal, vol. v., No. I, September 15, 1879, 
 p. 2. Editorial articles against immigration appeared in the official 
 organ of the Cigarmakers' Union before that, in the issues of June 10, 
 1878, and January 10, 1879. 
 
Old and New Immigration 79 
 
 ject of immigration, records a growing feeling of opposition 
 to foreign labor. Every reason which is urged to-day 
 against the admission of immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe is recited in that testimony, although 
 five sixths of the immigration in the fiscal year 1885, and 
 still more during the prior years, came from Canada and 
 Northern and Western Europe. 1 Thirteen years later an 
 inquiry addressed by the New York Bureau of Labor to 
 officers of labor organizations elicited the following reply 
 from the Brotherhood of Carpenters and Joiners No. 382, 
 of New York: "Immigrants from Northern Europe 
 Danes and Swedes interfere very much with the keeping 
 up of the wages in the trade. That is the principal thing 
 we find fault with." 3 
 
 The only apparent difference between the old immigra- 
 tion and the new is that of numbers. The reason why the 
 "old immigration ' ' is to-day viewed with greater favor than 
 the new is that there is much less of it. It is so stated in 
 the testimony of the representative of the railway brother- 
 hoods before the House Committee on Immigration and 
 Naturalization: 
 
 A good many people are apt to consider themselves better than some 
 other nationality. It is a matter of opinion, and, for my part, I am 
 not discussing this subject with any such narrow view of the situation. 
 I am not prepared to say that the Italian or the Slav or the Hungarian 
 or the Mexican has not the natural attributes that go to make up good 
 citizenship. ... It is not a question of whether or not they possess 
 those qualities. . . . The question is whether or not ... a foreigner 
 brought into this country is replacing or ruinously competing with some 
 one who is already here. 3 
 
 This is the question to which the attention of the unpreju- 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 63 and 87. 
 
 XVI Annual Report of New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1898, 
 p. 1047. 
 
 3 Hearings before Committee on Immigration and Naturalization, 
 
 H. R. 6ist Congress, pp. 251-252. 
 
8o -" Immigration and Labor 
 
 diced student of the immigration problem should address 
 itself. 
 
 NOTE: THE STATISTICS OF ITALIAN ILLITERACY 
 
 The Immigration Commission concedes that "it is impossible," from 
 a comparison of Italian statistics of illiteracy with our own statistics of 
 illiteracy among Italian immigrants, "to determine whether the pro- 
 portion of illiterates among Italian immigrants to the United States 
 is greater or less than among corresponding classes in Italy." 1 It 
 immediately seeks to weaken this conclusion by selecting for comparison 
 the statistics of illiteracy among persons contracting marriage, on the 
 assumption that "in the matter of age the marriage group would prob- 
 ably correspond rather closely to the immigrant group." As a result 
 of this selection it appears "that in 1905 36.9 per cent of the total 
 population contracting marriage and 48.8 per cent of the immigrants 
 were illiterate. " A comparison of the tables in question (28 and 32) 
 shows that the ratio of illiteracy among persons contracting marriage 
 in 1901 was 32.7 per cent for males and 46.1 per cent for females, 
 whereas among the population at large 21 years of age and over the 
 ratio of illiteracy was 43.9 per cent and 60.4 per cent respectively. 
 This difference is readily accounted for by the fact that the marriage 
 group is younger than the adult population as a whole, and the younger 
 generations have had the benefit of the progress of education in Italy; 
 the ratio of illiteracy among the adult population of both sexes in 1901 
 was 52.3 per cent, as compared with 63.4 per cent in 1882.' 
 
 On the other hand, while the immigrants contain a large percentage 
 of young men of marriageable age, yet there are among them quite a 
 number of men who have been married several years. Moreover, 
 "the marriage group ... is drawn from all sections of the country 
 and from all classes of the population, while immigrants are largely 
 from the peasant class of the more southern compartimenti. " It is 
 evident that a comparison of the marriage group with the immigrant 
 group must be unfavorable to the latter. If the immigrants are com- 
 pared with the total population 21 years of age and over, the results are 
 quite different. The percentage of illiteracy in Northern Italy, accord- 
 ing to the census of 1901, fluctuated between 16.8 and 46.8 per cent 
 for males and between 28.8 and 59.6 per cent for females 21 years of 
 age and over, whereas among North Italian immigrants of both sexes 
 14 years of age and over, for the fiscal year 1901, the ratio of illiteracy 
 was only 15.3 per cent. 3 In Southern Italy the percentage of illiteracy 
 among adults widely differs from one district to another; in some the 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, p. 192. 
 
 Ibid. t Table 27. Ibid., Tables 28 and 33. 
 
Old and New Immigration 81 
 
 ratio of illiteracy is lower, in some higher than among South Italian 
 immigrants. 
 
 Even if the marriage group furnished a proper standard for comparison 
 the variations of the illiteracy rate by administrative divisions would 
 make the results uncertain. In two districts the ratio of illiteracy 
 would be below and in two others above the percentage of illiteracy 
 among the North Italian immigrants. In Southern Italy two districts 
 show a higher percentage of illiteracy among males than the average 
 among South Italian immigrants of both sexes, and the percentage of 
 illiterates among women is in all but three districts higher than among 
 the immigrants of both sexes. The Commission would have been on 
 safer ground, had it adhered to its original conclusion, instead of specu- 
 lating on the basis of such incommensurable figures. 
 
CHAPTER IV 
 
 IMMIGRATION AND THE LABOR MARKET 
 
 THE main question in all present discussion of immigra- 
 tion is:*NDoes immigration injure the economic 
 interests of the American wage-earner? The demand for 
 restriction of immigration proceeds from the assumption 
 that immigration overcrowds the American labor market, 
 hordes of willing workers being driven by fear of starvation 
 to compete for one job. To remedy this evil foreign immi- 
 gration must be restricted: keep the "undesirable" immi- 
 grants out, and the American workingmen will be kept 
 busy. The more consistent advocates of this view, as 
 previously stated, regard all immigrants as undesirable. 
 It is an echo of the Malthusian theory, that population 
 increases faster than the means of subsistence, with this 
 modification, however, that the cause of the disproportion 
 is found, not in the natural propagation of the human species, 
 but in immigration, which is believed to outrun the oppor- 
 tunities of employment. In order to test the accuracy of 
 this assumption, let us first take an inventory of the indus- 
 trial progress of the United States compared with the growth 
 of population for the last twenty years. 
 
 The population of the continental United States increased 
 between 1890 and 1910 from 63,000,000 to 92,000,000, 
 *. e. t 46 percent. During the same period, the production 
 of coal in the United States more than trebled, the in- 
 crease being from 140,000,000 to 448,000,000, long tons. 1 
 As the exports of coal from the United States are insig- 
 
 1 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1911, Table 335. 
 
 82 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 83 
 
 nificant, x these- figures indicate that to-day three times as 
 much coal is consumed in this country as twenty years ago. 
 is thejoundation of modern industry. The increased 
 consumption ofcoal indicates that the 'consumption of 
 steam has increased threefold, i. e., that the whole American 
 industry has grown in proportion. The production of 
 steel, another basic article of modern industry, increased 
 during the twenty-year period 1889-1909 seven-fold, from 
 3,400,000 to 24,000,000 long tons. The production of 
 copper more than quadrupled, viz., from 101,000 to 488,000 
 tons. The number of ton-miles of freight carried over 
 American railways nearly trebled from 1890 to 1909, the 
 increase being from seventy-seven billions to two hundred 
 and nineteen billions. The total amount of bank clearings 
 in the United States likewise nearly trebled in the twenty- 
 year period between 1890 and 1910, having grown from 
 $58,000,000,000 to $169,000,000,000. 2 The increase in the 
 amount of bank clearings may be accepted as a fair index 
 of the aggregate industrial expansion. 3 Thus, while the 
 economic activities of the people of the United States have 
 trebled during the last twenty years, population has in- 
 creased by less than one half. 
 
 ' The introduction of labor-saving machinery has lessened 
 the potential demand for new laborers, yet the pace of 
 industrial development has been faster than the progress 
 of invention. The growing demand for bituminous coal 
 necessitated an increase of the working force from 192,000 
 in 1890 to 556,000 in 1910. 4 The number of railway em- 
 ployees increased from 749,301 in 1890 to 1,502,823 in 1909, 
 
 1 The exports of bituminous coal from the United States in 1891-1910 
 fluctuated between 1.5 and 3.1 per cent of the annual production. 
 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, p. 541. 
 
 8 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, Table No. 335. 
 
 3 Professor Irving Fisher estimates that the total trade of the United 
 States increased from $191,000,000,000 to $387,000,000,000 in the 
 thirteen years 1896-1909. The Purchasing Power of Money, p. 304. 
 
 4 Mineral Revmrces of the United States, 1908, pp. 25, 41. United 
 States Geological Survey. The Production of Coal in 191 o, p. 41. 
 
84 Immigration and Labor 
 
 t. e. t exactly 100 per cent. 1 The average number of wage- 
 earners employed in manufactures increased between 1889 
 and 1909 from 4,200,000 to 6,600,000, 2 i. e., 57 per cent. 
 
 ^The unbiased testimony of figures shows that the demand 
 for labor within the last twenty years has outrun the growth 
 of population, both through natural increase and through 
 immigration. The investigators of the Immigration Com- 
 mission sought to ascertain from employers of labor the 
 C" reason for employing immigrants/' and were told that 
 i"they found it necessary either to employ immigrant labor 
 or delay industrial advancement." 3 A number of specific 
 instances are quoted in the Commission's reports. In the 
 Birmingham iron and steel district, Alabama, where the 
 number of immigrants is insignificant, "the largest employ- 
 ers of labor . . . state that under normal conditions, at 
 the present stage of the industrial development of the 
 district, the ordinary labor supply which may be relied upon 
 continuously affords about 50 per cent of the total necessary 
 to operate all plants and mines at their full capacity." 4 
 In the centers of immigration, on the other hand, the 
 clothing manufacturers likewise claim "that the industry 
 has developed faster than the number of clothing workers 
 has increased." With the revival of business after the 
 depression of 1908 they found it "almost impossible to 
 keep their pay-rolls full." 5 
 
 According to an investigation made by the United States 
 Bureau of Labor, 
 
 the demand for laborers of all kinds in all lines of industry greatly ex- 
 ceeded the supply during the year 1906. One of the great lines of 
 railroad reported an increase in its construction and track gangs of 
 41 per cent in 1906 over 1905. . . . The men employed were all 
 
 1 Interstate Commerce Commission, Twelfth Annual Report on the 
 Statistics of Railways, p. 40, and Twenty-second Annual Report, p. 34. 
 
 9 Bureau of the Census, Manufactures, 1905, Part I., p. xxxvi. Census 
 Bureau's Preliminary Summary for 1909. "Advance Statement to the 
 Press of October 1 8, 1911. 3 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 140. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 151. 
 
 *Ibid. t vol. II, p. 411. 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 85 
 
 Italian immigrants. . . . Another large railway system reported an 
 fccrease of 44 per cent in this class of workers in 1906 over 1905. The 
 increase of one company was 24 per cent in this class of common labor. 
 An iron and steel company with a total of 147,343 employees in 1904 
 mcreased it to 180,158 employees in 1905 and to 217,109 in 1906. 
 
 Conditions are perhaps best summed up in this extract 
 from a letter received from the President of one of the 
 largest railroads: 
 
 Our work was delayed in both yearsigos and 1906 by the in- 
 ability to get workmen. This is true not only of railroads but of the 
 industries along our lines. Our patrons were constantly giving as the 
 excuse for not promptly unloading cars that they are unable to get 
 the laborers to do the work. There was not only a scarcity of common 
 laborers in the country, but we found it impossible, under existing con- 
 ditions, to get an adequate number of workmen for our shops. 1 
 
 Statements of employers of labor, however, are discounted ; 
 what is meant by "a scant labor supply" is simply, it is 
 thought, "the inability of the manufacturers and mine 
 operators to secure labor at the same wages in the face of 
 the growing labor needs of the country. " a Aside from the 
 admission implied in this interpretation, that the demand 
 for labor is growing faster than the supply, there is unin> 
 peachable evidence to the same effect in the report of the 
 Bureau of Labor, to which reference has been made above. 
 The Bureau's investigator examined the books of a number 
 of employment agencies for 1906 and found that they had 
 been unable to supply more than a fraction of their orders 
 for help. 3 
 
 1 Frank J. Sheridan: " Italian, Slavic, and Hungarian Unskilled Im- 
 migrant Laborers in the United States." Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, 
 No. 72, pp. 424-425- 
 
 a Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t pp. 17, 140. 
 
 a "A personal examination of the books of record of another agency, 
 covering a period of eight months, from April I to November 30, 1906, 
 showed that 165 employers in the States of New York, New Jersey, 
 Connecticut, Pennsylvania, and Virginia made application for 8668 
 Italian laborers from this one agency. The agency supplied fewer than 
 f 500. Another agency, where no fees were charged, had applications 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 Doubtless, demand and supply in the labor market are 
 fluctuating. During the twenty-year period under con- 
 sideration, this country has gone through two industrial 
 crises, when great numbers of wage-earners were suddenly 
 thrown out of employment. The question is, what, if 
 any, is the interdependence between the vicissitudes of 
 the labor market and immigration? 
 
 The Industrial Commission, in 1901, from a comparative 
 study of the number of immigrants and price index numbers 
 .for a period of sixty years, arrived at the conclusion that 
 ''"immigration follows business conditions in obedience to 
 the opportunities for employment : In times of business ex- 
 pansion, when capital is seeking investment and the re- 
 sources of the country are being eagerly developed . . . 
 immigrants enter in increasing numbers to take a share of 
 the increasing wages and employment, but in times of 
 business depression their numbers decline. " x 
 
 The report of the Industrial Commission appeared after 
 a decade of declining immigration. Has the unprecedented 
 immigration of recent years changed its relation to business 
 conditions in this country? 
 
 A comparative view of the fluctuations of business and 
 immigration for the past thirty years, since the tide has 
 set in from Eastern and Southern Europe, can be gained 
 from a glance at Diagram I. 2 It will be observed that the 
 curves representing the production of coal, the volume of 
 railway freight, bank clearings, and immigration run in 
 
 in seven months for 37,058, and could supply but 3705 newly arrived 
 Italian immigrants. One effect of the scarcity is reported by an Italian 
 agency as follows: 
 
 " ' Since about July, 1906, on account of the great scarcity, employers 
 pay from $3.00 to $5.00 per man for common laborers. Not for twenty- 
 two years have there been such high fees offered. Since the demand set 
 in the laborer pays no fees.' " (Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 72, 
 
 pp. 424-425-) 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. 308, 309. See 
 also chart opposite p. 305. 
 
 3 Based uoon the figures of the Statistical Abstract of the United States. 
 
DIAGRAM I. 
 
 IMMIORANT5 ARRIVED. TENS OF THOUSANDS 
 PRODUCTION OF COAL, luwr - Z.000.000 LONG TONS 
 LWAY FREIGHT. BILLIONS OF (SHORT) TON HUES 
 .US BANK CLEARINGS: BILLIONS OF DOLLARS 
 
 COMMERCIAL FAILURES. IU 
 
 500,000 
 
 "\ 
 
 / 
 
 *>/ 
 
 r 
 
 1 
 
 Ly 
 
 
 I 
 
 I. Immigration and business conditions, 1880-1910. 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 harmony. On the other hand, the decrease of immigration 
 from 1880 to 1899 runs almost parallel with the increase of 
 commercial failures, and vice versa. During the following 
 years of prosperity the amount of commercial failures 
 showed little variation, and the curve of immigration was 
 following the lines of industrial expansion. The years since 
 the last panic again show a parallelism between the decline 
 of immigration and the increase of failures, on the one hand, 
 ajid industrial activity, on the other. 
 
 It must be borne in mind that the immigration figures 
 represent gross additions to the population of the United 
 States. Attention has frequently been called, however, 
 to the vast disparity between the increase of the foreign- 
 born population from one census to another and the total 
 immigration for the intervening period. The latest figures 
 on the subject are given in Table 7. 
 
 TABLE 7. 
 
 IMMIGRATION COMPARED WITH INCREASE OF FOREIGN-BORN POPULA- 
 TION. 1 
 
 Decade 
 
 Immigration 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Increase in foreign-born population 
 
 Number 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Per cent ratio 
 to immigration 
 
 1850-1860 
 
 2,598 
 2,315 
 2,812 
 
 5,247 
 3,688 
 
 8,795 
 5,565 
 
 1,928 
 1,428 
 I,H3 
 2,570 
 1,092 
 3,175 
 358 
 
 74 
 62 
 40 
 50 
 29 
 36 
 6 
 
 1860-1870 
 
 1870-1880 
 
 1880-1890 
 
 1890-1900 
 
 19001910 
 
 1910-1920 2 
 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I., pp. 64, 135. XIII. Census. Popu- 
 lation, vol. i., p. 781. 
 
 J The comparative figures for the last decade do not include Orientals, the preliminary 
 returns of the XIV. Census made public by the Bureau of the Census being confined to 
 foreign-born white. The total number of white immigrants for the period from July 
 i, 1910, to June 30, 1920, has been computed from the Report of the Commissioner - 
 General of Immigration for 1920, Table XV., pp. 181-182. 
 
 The difference between gross immigration and the net 
 increase of the foreign-born population is the combined 
 result of mortality and emigration. As the foreign-born 
 population increases, an ever larger number of new arrivals 
 
DIAGRAM II. 
 
 II. Movement of third-class passengers between the United 
 States and European pofts, 1899-1909 (Tens of Thousands) 
 
 89 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 merely fill up the places of their predecessors claimed by 
 death. The foreign-born white population of the United 
 States in 1920 was twice as great as in iSSo 1 ; accordingly 
 twice as many immigrants were required in 1920 as forty 
 years before only to keep the numbers of foreign-born sta- 
 tionary. The statistics of the inward and outward trans- 
 atlantic passenger traffic are generally taken to represent 
 the immigration and emigration movement. 2 The respec- 
 tive figures for 1899-1909 are reproduced in Table 8 from the 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, Table 26, and 
 plotted in Diagram II. on p. 89. 
 
 TABLE 8. 
 
 MOVEMENT OF THIRD CLASS PASSENGERS BETWEEN THE UNITED STATES 
 AND EUROPEAN PORTS DURING THE CALENDAR YEARS 
 1899 TO 1909. (THOUSANDS.) 
 
 Year 
 
 West-bound 
 passengers 
 
 East-bound 
 passengers 
 
 Net immigration ( +) 
 or emigration (. ) 
 
 1899 
 
 381 
 
 118 
 
 +263 
 
 1900 
 
 503 
 
 156 
 
 +347 
 
 1901 
 
 545 
 
 141 
 
 +404 
 
 1902 
 
 753 
 
 177 
 
 +576 
 
 1903 
 
 887 
 
 252 
 
 +635 
 
 1904 
 
 762 
 
 371 
 
 +391 
 
 1905 
 
 1004 
 
 244 
 
 +760 
 
 1906 
 
 1223 
 
 338 
 
 +885 
 
 1907 
 
 1378 
 
 555 
 
 +823 
 
 1908 
 
 420 
 
 657 
 
 -237 
 
 1909 
 
 750 
 
 287 
 
 +463 
 
 1 The foreign-born white population increased from 6,559,679 in 
 1880 to 13,703,987 in 1920. 
 
 2 Richmond-Mayo-Smith: " Immigration and the Foreign-Born Pop- 
 ulation." Publications of the American Statistical Association, vol. 
 iii., pp. 305-306. Roland P. Falkner: "Some Aspects of the Immigra- 
 tion Problem." Political Science Quarterly, March, 1904, p. 38. 
 
 Our statistics of emigration do not go back of the fiscal year ended 
 June 30, 1908. Nor can they be accepted as quite reliable, being of 
 necessity based upon the declarations of the aliens at the time of their 
 departure. The total number of departing aliens for the period from 
 July i, 1907, to June 30, 1920, exceeded the number of avowed "emi- 
 grants" by 2,513,000, whereas the total number of admitted aliens ex- 
 ceeded the number of immigrants only by 1,867,000, which shows that 
 
IS 
 
 \/ 
 
 
 III. Monthly immigration and emigration, from July, 1907, to 
 May, 1909 (thousands). 
 
 646,000 persons classified as "non-emigrant aliens," i, e. t 26 per cent, 
 of that class, did not return to the United States. See Appendix, Table 
 XXX. 
 
 91 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 It will be observed that the tide of immigration was rising 
 until 1907, with a slight set-back during the Presidential 
 year 1904. During the industrial crisis of 1908 immigration 
 dropped at once nearly a million, compared with the high- 
 water mark of the previous year, while emigration from the 
 United States was about twice the number of 1906. The 
 result was a net loss of nearly a quarter of a million through 
 emigration. In 1909, with returning business confidence 
 immigration increased and emigration receded to its nor- 
 mal level of the years 1903- 1906.* The same tendencies 
 appear still more clearly if the returns are compared by 
 months, as in Table 9, and Diagram III. on p. 91.* 
 
 TABLE 9. 
 
 AVERAGE MONTHLY IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION. (THOUSANDS), 
 1907-1909. 
 
 
 
 
 Net immigration( -f ) 
 
 Period 
 
 Admitted 
 
 Departed 
 
 or emigration ( ) 
 
 July i-October 31 , 1907 
 November, 1907 
 
 116 
 132 
 
 47 
 94 
 
 + 69 
 
 + 38 
 
 Dec. i, 1907-Aug. 31, 1908 
 
 45 
 
 59 
 
 ~ 14 
 
 Sept. i, I9o8-Feb. 28, 1909 
 
 6l 
 
 33 
 
 . + 28 
 
 March- April, 1909 
 
 137 
 
 24 
 
 + 113 
 
 1 An examination of the Italian statistics of emigration to the United 
 States and the return movement from the United States leads the Immi- 
 gration Commission to the conclusion "that as a rule the causes which 
 retard emigration also accelerate the exodus from the United States. . . . 
 The effect of financial and industrial depressions in the United States 
 is clearly apparent. . . . The most conspicuous instance . . . 
 occurred in the year 1894, following the industrial depression of that 
 period. In that year the outward movement from Italy decreased and 
 the inward movement increased to such an extent that the number re- 
 turning was 848 to every I ooo emigrating. The same tendency was shown 
 again in 1904, immediately following the financial depression of the pre- 
 ceding year. " Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, p. 229. 
 
 2 Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1908, 
 p. 228, and 1910, p. 14. The monthly figures are for immigrant and 
 emigrant aliens, as defined in the statistics of the Bureau of Immigration. 
 These two classes are not identical with third-class passengers arriving 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 
 
 Prom July I, to October 31, 1907, immigration and emi- 
 gration went on normally. The latter part of October 
 witnessed the outbreak of the crisis, and the next month 
 emigration doubled. Immigration still remained normal, 
 inasmuch as those who arrived here in November had left 
 their homes before the crisis. But from December immigra- 
 tion dropped to one third of the number of arrivals in No- 
 vember. During the next nine months emigration exceeded 
 immigration by 14,000 persons monthly. From September 
 I, 1908, the situation began to improve, and the number of 
 immigrants went up again, while departures went down. 
 In the spring of the next year immigration and emigration 
 resumed their normal relation. It is evident that the 
 immigration movement promptly responds to the business 
 situation in the UnitedyStates. 
 
 The question arises: How does immigration adjust itself 
 to business conditions in America? The method by which 
 this adjustment is effected is thus described by the Immi- 
 gration Commission: 
 
 It is entirely safe to assert that letters from persons who have emi- 
 grated to friends at home have betp the immediate cause of by far the 
 greater part of the remarkable movement from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe to the United States during the past twenty-five years. There 
 is hardly a village or community in Southern Italy and Sicily that has 
 not contributed a portion of its population to swell the tide of emigration 
 to the United States, and the same is true of large areas of Austria, 
 Hungary, Greece, Turkey, and the Balkan States. ... It was fre- 
 quently stated to members of the Commission that letters from persons 
 who had emigrated to America were passed from hand to hand until 
 most of the emigrants' friends and neighbors were acquainted with the 
 contents. In periods of industrial activity, as a rule, the letters so 
 circulated contain optimistic references to wages and opportunities for 
 employment in the United States. ... The reverse is true during 
 seasons of industrial depression in the United States. At such times 
 intending emigrants are quickly informed by their friends in the United 
 
 and departing. Those aliens who go to Europe with the expectation 
 of returning may never come again, yet they are not included among 
 " emigrant aliens. " As a result, the net emigration is lower in this 1 
 in the preceding table. 
 
94 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 States relative to conditions of employment, and a great falling off in 
 the tide of emigration is the immediate result. . . . Emigrants as a 
 rule are practically assured that employment awaits them in America 
 before they leave their homes for ports of embarkation. ... Ir, fact 
 it may be said that immigrants, or at least newly -arrived immigrants, 
 are substantially the agencies which keep the American labor market 
 supplied with unskilled laborers from Europe. ... As a rule, each 
 immigrant simply informs his nearest friends that employment can be 
 had and advises them to come. It is these personal appeals which, 
 more than all other agencies, promote and regulate the tide of European 
 emigration to America. 1 
 
 These conclusions of the Immigration Commission are 
 corroborated by Table 10. 
 
 TABLE TO. 
 IMMIGRANTS' CONNECTIONS IN THE UNITED STATES.* 
 
 Immigrant aliens 
 admitted 
 
 Numbers 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Percentages 
 
 1908 
 
 1909 
 
 1910 
 
 1908 
 
 1909 
 
 1910 
 
 Total 
 
 783 
 
 752 
 
 1042 
 
 100 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 82 
 13 
 5 
 
 Going to join: 
 Relative . 
 
 596 
 128 
 
 59 
 
 t 
 583 
 
 122 
 
 47 
 
 857 
 133 
 52 
 
 76 
 
 16 
 
 8 
 
 77 
 17 
 6 
 
 Friend 
 
 Neither 
 
 
 4 It appears that most of the immigrants come to join 
 relatives, and that only a small proportion of those who 
 land here have neither relatives nor friends to meet them 
 on arrival. This percentage is much smaller for the new 
 immigration than for the old, viz., 3 per cent for the former 
 as against 10.6 per cent for the latter. 3 
 
 There is a remarkable coincidence of the percentage 
 ratios for the fiscal years ending June 30, 1908 and 1909. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 187-189. 
 
 a Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1908, 
 p. 15; 1909, p. 23; 1910, p. 21. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, Table 38. The figures 
 are for 1908 and 1909. 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 95 
 
 Both were partly affected by the crisis. On the other hand, 
 the year 1910 shows an addition of 274,000, i. e. 47 per cent, 
 to the number of immigrants coming to join their relatives, 
 while the number of persons who came in 1908-1910 to 
 join friends, and the number of those who seemingly had 
 neither relatives nor friends in the United States, exhibit 
 only slight fluctuations from year to year. This means 
 that, as soon as conditions improved, the first thought of 
 the older immigrants was of their kin whom they had left 
 behind; friends came next. 
 
 The correctness of this interpretation is supported by 
 Table n, which shows the fluctuations in the number of 
 immigrants whose passage was paid by their American 
 relatives, compared with the number of dependents ad- 
 mitted in official terminology, "no occupation (including 
 women and children) " and also the fluctuations in the 
 number of persons whose passage was paid by persons 
 "other than self or relative," i. e. by friends. 1 The fiscal 
 year ending June 30, 1908, included four prosperous months 
 from July to October, 1907. Moreover, many of those 
 who reached the United States later in the year had been 
 provided with steamship tickets before the crisis. Their 
 American relatives and friends must have been saving 
 the money with which their passage was paid, for some 
 months previous to their landing. Steamship tickets are 
 quite commonly sold on small weekly payments. The full 
 effect of the crisis therefore manifested itself during the 
 next fiscal year (beginning July I, 1908), when the number 
 of immigrants who arrived on tickets prepaid by their 
 American relatives dropped twenty per cent. In 1910 
 their number again came up to the level of 1908. In 1908 
 the number of such immigrants exceeded by 32,000 the 
 number of dependents coming to join their relatives who 
 had preceded them. Evidently some of the resident aliens 
 had raised the means to send for their brothers, sisters, and 
 
 ' Report of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1908, pp. 15, 
 
 35; 1999, w- 23. 4*; ifit, 2I - * 
 
9 6 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 J 
 
 other self-supporting relatives, in addition to the members 
 of their immediate households. In 1909 the number of 
 immigrants assisted by their American relatives was barely 
 equal to the total number of dependents who came to join 
 their husbands and fathers. Apparently while employ- 
 ment was scarce the foreign-born workman could spare no 
 money to send for his more distant relatives. In 1910 im- 
 proved business conditions again brought to this country 
 quite a number of breadwinners (14,000) whose passage 
 was paid by their American relatives. The number of 
 immigrants assisted by their American friends showed 
 similar fluctuations. 
 
 TABLE it. 
 
 ASSISTED IMMIGRATION 
 
 Year' Ending June 30 
 
 1908 
 
 1909 
 
 1910 
 
 Assisted immigrants (thousands) : 
 Passage paid, by relative . . 
 
 275 
 
 22O 
 
 27J. 
 
 Dependents 
 
 24. -I 
 
 221 
 
 */4 
 
 2OO 
 
 
 
 
 
 Difference 
 
 +32 
 
 I 
 
 + 14 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 IO 
 
 8 
 
 12 
 
 
 
 
 
 * Another potent agency which regulates immigration is 
 the great number of returning immigrants. As a rule, 
 says the Immigration Commission, they are those who 
 have succeeded. "The money they can show makes a 
 vivid impression. They are dispensers of information and 
 inspiration, and are often willing to follow up the inspira- 
 tion by loans to prospective emigrants." 1 During the 
 ten -year period 1900-1909, three million people returned to 
 Europe from the United States. (See Table 8 above.) 
 Compared with this army of promoters of immigration, 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vqj. 4, p. 58. 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 97 
 
 the much blamed steamship agent fades into insignificance. 
 A simple calculation will show that the number of steamship 
 agents is grossly exaggerated by popular imagination. In 
 order to make something by "stimulating immigration," 
 an agent must sell at least one ticket a week; his commission 
 on $37, which is the average cost of passage from Europe, 
 could not be too great at that. A good many tickets are 
 prepaid on this side; yet if every steamship ticket were 
 sold through an agent, the annual emigration of a million 
 persons could barely support twenty thousand agents. 
 This scarcely equals one per cent of the volunteer force of 
 immigration promoters who have returned from America 
 within the past ten years, with every allowance made for 
 duplications. It is clearly against all sense of proportion to 
 magnify the "propaganda" of a few thousand ticket agents 
 into a contributing cause of this modern Volkerwanderung. * 
 The facts brought to light by the investigation of the Immi- 
 gration Commission in Europe will tend to dissipate this 
 popular delusion. The Commission found that in Greece, 
 which "according to its population furnishes more immi- 
 grants to the United States than any other country . . . 
 solicitation by steamship companies probably plays rela- 
 tively a small part even as a contributory cause of the 
 movement." In Austria "government officials and others 
 interested in the emigration situation expressed the belief 
 that the solicitations of agents had little effect on the 
 emigration movement, which was influenced almost entirely 
 by economic conditions." Unquestionably, steamship 
 agents in all parts of Europe solicit business in competition 
 with one another, but they do it, as Mr. T. V. Powderly 
 has found, "much as insurance agents do. ... One 
 method adopted is to translate editorials and articles from 
 American newspapers relative to the prosperity of the 
 United States, which articles are distributed among pros- 
 
 1 There are some people who similarly believe that the trade-union 
 movement of our days is "stimulated" by the "labor agitators," 
 walking delegates, and business agents of the unions. 
 
98 Immigration and Labor 
 
 pective emigrants. " The Immigration Commission learned 
 in Hungary that steamship agents addressed "personal 
 letters to prospective emigrants advising how to leave 
 Hungary without the consent of the government. Letters 
 of this nature were presented to the Commission. Some 
 of them are accompanied by crudely drawn maps indicating 
 the location of all the Hungarian control stations on the 
 Austrian border, and the routes of travel by which such 
 stations can be avoided." 1 It is clear that such letters 
 can appeal only to those who have already made up their 
 minds to emigrate. The immigrant is not as simple-mindea 
 and credulous as he is popularly represented to be. ' ' Several 
 American States have attempted to attract immigrants by 
 the distribution in Europe of literature advertising the 
 attractions of such States. A few States ha. ... .om- 
 missioners to various countries for the purpose of inducing 
 immigration, but although some measure of success has 
 attended such efforts, the propaganda has had little effect 
 on the immigration movement as a whole. ' ' 2 There appears 
 to be no sound reason Why the "editorials and articles 
 from American newspapers relative to the prosperity of 
 the United States, " circulated by a steamship agent, should 
 have a greater effect with the European peasant than the 
 literature distributed by an official representative of an 
 American State. The conclusion reached by the Immigra- 
 tion Commission is that "immigration from Europe pro- 
 ceeds according to well-defined individual plans rather than 
 in a haphazard way. " 3 The Commission qualifies this con- 
 clusion by the statement that since "selling steerage tickets 
 to America is the sole or chief occupation of large numbers 
 of persons in Southern and Eastern Europe," and since 
 "these local agents, as a rule, solicit business," they "con- 
 sequently encourage emigration." 4 This argument might 
 be made broader by substituting the principal for the agent : 
 it is the steamship companies that encourage emigration by 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, p. 63. 
 
 2 Ibid., vol. i, p. 192. 3 Ibid., p. 188. 4 Ibid., vol. 4, p. 62. 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 99 
 
 making-it their business to sell steerage tickets to America, 
 for it is a self-evident truth that should the steamship 
 companies discontinue the sale of steerage tickets, emigra- 
 tion would be discouraged. Inasmuch, however, as the 
 Immigration Commission recognizes the difficulty for the 
 ordinary laborer in Southern and Eastern Europe to raise 
 the price of a steerage ticket, "no matter how strong the 
 desire to emigrate may be, " the question is, by what means 
 the local agents encourage the emigration of impecunious 
 laborers who have no relatives or friends in America willing 
 to advance them the price of a ticket. The popular answer, 
 is that the "new immigration" is largely "stimulated" byl 
 employers of labor masquerading as "friends" of the immi- 
 grant It is believed that "the ends of the earth have 
 been ranra 'died in the search for the low standards of living 
 combined with patient industriousness. " * 
 
 Representatives of labor speak indiscriminately of all 
 Slav and Italian immigration as "imported," in other 
 words as contract labor. The truth is that the frequency 
 of the practice in recent times has been greatly exaggerated 
 by popular imagination. The investigations of the Im- 
 migration Commission, both in the United States and in 
 Europe, failed to disclose any evidence of systematic im- 
 portation of contract laborers. 2 In the Connellsville coke 
 region of Pennsylvania, old inhabitants remember that as 
 far back as 1882 "some companies had agents in -Europe 
 soliciting and encouraging the immigration of Slovaks, 
 Poles, and Bohemians . . . and some immigrants may have 
 been imported as contract laborers. 1 ' 3 Of what little conse- 
 quence these importations could have been, is clear from the 
 fact that eight years later, at the census of 1890, there were 
 
 1 John R. Commons: Races and Immigrants in America, p. 152. 
 
 a The inquiries made by the Commission in Europe "did not disclose 
 that actual contracts involving promises of employment between 
 employers in the United States and laborers in Europe were responsible 
 for any considerable part of the present emigration movement." Reports, 
 vol. 4 p. 60. No figures or specific cases are cited. See also, further, 
 Chapter XIX. 3 /&*, vol. 6, p. 257. 
 
ioo Immigration and Labor 
 
 enumerated in Fayette and Westmoreland counties (the 
 Connellsviile region) 4788 natives of Hungary, Bohemia, 
 and Poland, of both sexes, all ages, and all occupations. 1 
 It is quite conceivable that in the case of a strike a great 
 corporation might have resorted to the importation of a 
 force of strikebreakers regardless of cost. There is a 
 "legend" in the Pennsylvania anthracite field that during 
 a strike in 1870 a breaker belonging to Eckley B. Coxe was 
 burned down, whereupon he secured through his superin^ 
 tendent "two shiploads of his Hungarian countrymen to 
 man the new structure. There is no evidence of any further 
 importations of immigrants by the mine owners, since there han 
 been no necessity for such an effort. 112 With immigration 
 running into hundreds of thousands annually, there i7 
 no economic advantage in importing a few thousand a 
 year, as they could have no effect upon labor conditions in 
 general. 3 On the other hand, their importation would in> 
 volve an outlay of money for their passage without any 
 guarantee of repayment, as the contract of employment 
 could not be enforced in law in case the laborer chose to 
 break it. It is not usual for an employer of labor in this 
 country to advance a sum equal to a month's wages without 
 any security to a laborer in his employ. That the personal 
 credit of the laborer should be enhanced by his absence 
 from the United States hardly accords with common ex- 
 perience. Apart from economic considerations, the Immi- 
 gration Commission finds that "owing to the rigidity of the 
 law and the fact that special provision is made for its en- 
 forcement there are probably at the present time relatively 
 few actual contract laborers admitted." 4 This conclusion 
 
 1 Population of the United States, XI. Census, vol. i., p. 654 (com- 
 puted). 
 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 16, p. 661. 
 
 * A sound view of the question is taken by Prof. Adams and Dr. 
 Sumner in their book on I&bor Problems, wHere they say that under the 
 influence of the increase of immigration it is no longer profitable to 
 "induce** immigration (pp. 90-91). 
 
 Reports, vol. i,p. 29. 
 
Immigration and the Labor Market 101 
 
 ought to be accepted as final. It would be impossible for 
 any corporation or labor agent to operate on a large scale 
 in violation of the law without being detected. Human 
 experience has no record of a secret guarded by a multitude. 
 The few violations of the contract labor law that elude the 
 vigilance of the immigration officials cannot affect the labor 
 market. 
 
 'The supply of immigrant labor is regulated by free com- 
 petition, like that of any other commodity. It may some- 
 times exceed the demand and at other times fall short of 
 it ; in the long run, however, supply adjusts itself to demand. 
 If we compare the totals for industrial cycles, including 
 years of panic, of depression, and of prosperity, we find a 
 remarkable regularity in the ratio of immigration to popula- 
 tion. In Table 12 the addition to population through 
 immigration during the twenty-year period 1891-1910 is 
 collated with the corresponding figures for the preceding 
 two periods of equal length. 
 
 TABLE 12. 
 
 POPULATION AND IMMIGRATION 
 
 Census Population 
 
 Immigration for twenty years following 
 
 Year 
 
 Thousands 
 
 Thousands 
 
 Percentage ratio to 
 population at 
 preceding census 
 
 Period 
 
 1850 
 
 23,192 
 38,558 
 62,622 
 
 5,019 
 8,059 
 
 12,483 
 
 21.2 
 20.9 
 19.9 
 
 1851-1870 
 1871-1890 
 I89I-I910 
 
 l8?O. . . 
 
 5* 1800. . 
 
 f> 
 
 \ \-> 
 
 These figures show that during the past sixty years, not- 
 Jlvithstanding the fluctuations from year to year, in the 
 long run the ratio of immigration to population has been 
 well-nigh constant, with a slightly declining tendency 
 as population has grown. Although the total number of 
 immigrants for the period 1891-1910 was 50 per cent in 
 
/ 
 ^ 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 tiie total for the preceding period, yet the addition 
 to population was relatively smaller during the later period. 
 It has also been shown (see Table 2) that the per cent 
 distribution of immigrants by occupations has undergone 
 little change during the past half-century, notwithstanding 
 the rise and fall in numbers from decade to decade. The 
 ratio of skilled mechanics has during the last thirty years 
 remained at 20 per cent, while unskilled laborers have made 
 up 57 per cent of all immigrants. This regularity indicates 
 that the demand for labor determines the character, as 
 as the volume of immigration. 
 
CHAPTER V . 
 
 THE DEMAND FOR LABOR IN AGRICULTURE 
 
 THE preference of the "new" immigrants for city employ- 
 ments over agricultural pursuits is viewed with appre- 
 hension by philanthropists and sociologists. It is evident, 
 however, that even the "desirable" immigrant from North- 
 ern and Western Europe who brings with him on an average 
 $55* lacks the necessary means to rent a farm, let alone to 
 buy one. 2 At best he can only obtain employment as a 
 farm hand, which depends primarily upon the demand for 
 farm labor. And here he is confronted with the fact that 
 the American farmer cannot keep his own sons on the farm. 
 The industrial development of the United States has 
 manifested itself in a relative decrease, and in some sections 
 in a numerical decrease of the rural population. In New 
 England and New York an actual depopulation of the rural 
 districts was recorded by the census of 1890. The next 
 census showed a loss of rural population in New Jersey, 
 Delaware, Ohio, and Kansas. Maryland and Illinois sus- 
 tained similar losses from 1880 to 1890, but recovered them 
 within the next ten years. 3 The published bulletins of the 
 last census show a numerical decrease of the rural population 
 in the following States of the Central West: 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4 (in press). 
 
 3 The average value per farm, exclusive of real estate, in 1900, 
 amounted to $1173. H. W. Quaintance: The Influence of Farm 
 Machinery en Production and Labor, p. 58. 
 
 * Supplementary Analysis, XII. Census, p. 78, Table XXXIX 
 
 103 
 
104 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 13. 
 
 DECREASE OF THE POPULATION OF RURAL TERRITORY, I90O-I9IO 
 
 State . Number Per cent 
 
 Illinois 111,963 7.0 
 
 Indiana 132,266 9.5 
 
 Iowa 152,673 12. i 
 
 Kansas 4,919 0.5 
 
 Michigan 9,946 0.8 
 
 Missouri 133.489 8.0 
 
 Ohio 93,055 5.3 
 
 Wisconsin 8,201 0.7 
 
 Even where the total rural population of a State has 
 increased since 1900, the maps given in the census bul- 
 letins show a few agricultural counties with a declining 
 population. 
 
 This depopulation of rural territory is due to emigration 
 of native Americans of native stock. The figures for 1910 
 are as yet not available; the census of 1900 recorded in Kan- 
 sas a loss of 2.8 per cent of the native population of native 
 parentage in settlements of less than 2500 inhabitants, and 
 in Nebraska a loss of i .3 per cent of the same element. In 
 New England, New York, and New Jersey the loss was still 
 greater; the maximum was reached in Connecticut, viz., 
 16.7 per cent. 1 
 
 The popular way to account for a social phenomenon is 
 to seek an explanation in the personal tastes and dislikes of 
 individuals or racial groups. "Much has been said of a 
 mad rush to cities," said Prof. Charles H. Cooley before 
 the Michigan Political Science Association, in July, 1902, 
 "and the movement has often been spoken of as if it were 
 altogether a kind of dissipation, like going to the saloon. 
 But if there were no solider ground for the migration than 
 this we should find the migrants plunged into pauperism 
 and vice after they get to the cities, instead of pursuing 
 useful remunerative labor as is ordinarily the case. The 
 real causes of the decrease of rural population are chiefly 
 economic. " These causes affect the native and the foreign 
 
 1 Supplementary Analysis, XII. Census, pp. 620-627, Tables 10 and 1 1. 
 
fei 
 
 m 
 
 DIAGRAM IV. 
 I 1 
 
 fifctin 
 
 'IC(JU 
 
 OtKt 
 
 I I m 
 
 IV. Relative per-capita production of coal, agricultural staples 
 
 and live stock. 
 
 105 
 
io6 Immigration and Labor 
 
 current to the cities alike. Since the early days of Irish 
 and German immigration the growing industries of the 
 cities have offered a better market for labor than agri- 
 culture. A comparative view of the demand for laboi 
 in agriculture and in industry since 1870 is furnished in 
 Diagram IV, where the per capita production of the principal 
 agricultural staples and live stock is compared with the 
 per capita production of coal, the latter being chosen as 
 the measure of industrial expansion. 1 Whereas the pro- 
 duction of coal has quadrupled, the increase of the output 
 of cotton is only about 90 per cent, the increase of other 
 farm products less than 50 per cent, and stock breeding 
 has not kept pace with the increase of population. It is 
 patent that the demand for farm hands must have lagged 
 far behind the demand for labor in manufacturing, mining 
 and transportation. 
 
 The relative number of persons engaged in agriculture 
 fell from 21.79 per cent of the total population in 1840 to 
 X 543 P er cen t in 1870. This decrease was not confined 
 to any one State or section, but was universal, with the 
 exception of Florida. In New York and all New England 
 States there was during the same period an absolute de- 
 crease of the agricultural population from 869,000 to 697,000, 
 i. ., 20 per cent. 2 The revolution wrought in American 
 farming by the industrial development of the past seventy 
 years has tended to reduce the demand for labor on the 
 farm. 
 
 The American farm of the first half of the nineteenth cen- 
 tury was the seat of a highly diversified business, comprising 
 not only the raising of food and of material for clothing, 
 
 x The figures for Diagram IV are taken from an article by Prof. 
 Homer C. Price on "The Reorganization of American Farming" in 
 Popular Science Monthly , May, 1910, p. 464; the Census Report on Mines 
 and Quarries, 1902, p. 669, Table 6; and Statistical Abstract, 1911, 
 Table No. 335. The figures for agricultural products are averages for 
 each decade beginning 1866-1875 and for the quadrennial period 1905- 
 1908. Coal production per capita is for each census year since 1870. 
 
 3 Bulletin of the Department of Labor, No. 1 1 , pp. 400, 402. 
 
The Demand for Labor in Agriculture 107 
 
 but also the preparation and manufacture of these pro- 
 ducts. 1 Wakefield, in 1833, gave the following description 
 of the American farmer: 
 
 Free Americans, who cultivate the soil, follow many other occupations. 
 Some portion of the furniture and tools which they use is commonly 
 made by themselves. They frequently build their own houses, and 
 carry to market, at whatever distance, the produce of their own industry. 
 They are spinners and weavers, they make soap and candles, as well as, 
 in many cases, shoes and clothes for their own use. 2 
 
 With such a variety of occupations there was work for a 
 hired man at all seasons of the year. But the development 
 of manufactures has differentiated from the farming business 
 one industry after another and removed them from the 
 farm. 3 The time during which a hired man can be kept 
 employed on the farm has been reduced in consequence to a 
 few months in the year. 
 
 Still until the middle of the nineteenth century the mills 
 were quite commonly run by water power, the supply of 
 which determined their location. The small country towns 
 were alive with little industries, which offered to the farm 
 laborer a prospect of employment during the winter when 
 work was scarce on the farm. 4 But the general substitution 
 cf steam for water power and the consequent concentration 
 of industry removed the factories from the small towns to 
 
 1 L. H. Bailey: The State and the Farmer, pp. 6, 7. 
 
 3 E. G. Wakefield: England and America, vol. i., pp. 21,22. 
 
 a "At the present time, throughout probably the greater part of the 
 country . . . butter-making is ordinarily done away from the farm, " 
 but in 1870, "butter was made ... on the farms and as part of farm 
 work. The development of the agricultural implement industry is 
 another instance. The manufacture of the implements and machines 
 from being a feature of farm work has become a distinct branch of 
 manufactures, employing, according to the returns of the XII census, 
 during the census year reported on, an 'average number' of 46,582 
 persons besides 10,046 salaried officials, clerks, etc." M. W. Quaintance , 
 loc. cit., pp. 44-45, 74. 
 
 * Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. x., pp. cl. and 889. Report 
 o*,,Cdnditi<w of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in the United States, 
 vM.ix.,p.48. 
 
io8 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the great manufacturing cities. The opportunity to earn 
 a full year's wages in a rural community was gone, and the 
 farm laborer followed the factory to the city. x 
 
 Along with the progress of division of labor between 
 farm and factory, the invention of labor-saving machinery 
 tended to displace the wage-earner from agriculture. Down 
 to the middle of the nineteenth century the agricultural 
 methods of the American farmer were as primitive as those 
 of the Russian peasant of the present. The first patent for 
 a cast-iron plow was granted as early as 1797, but it took 
 many years before it had overcome the prejudice of the 
 farmers who believed that the use of cast-iron "poisoned the 
 land." About 1850, cast-iron plows had come into 
 general use, but grass was still mowed with the scythe, 
 grain was cut with the sickle and threshed with the flail. 
 Flailing and winnowing grain was the chief farm work of 
 the winter. As late as the year 1870, the editor of the 
 New American Farm Book questioned the advisability of 
 using the large threshing machines and advised for the 
 "moderate farmer" the use of a hand thresher as the more 
 economical, permitting the work to be done "in winter, 
 when there is more leisure to do it." Corn was planted 
 by hand, cultivated with the hoe, and shelled by scraping 
 the ears against the handle of a frying pan or the blade of a 
 shovel. The cultivation of a farm in this crude way re- 
 quired a great deal of labor and sustained a steady demand 
 for farm help in all seasons. To-day "there is hardly a 
 phase of farm work that has not been essentially changed 
 by the introduction of some new implement or machine. " 
 For planting corn 
 
 the farmer now uses a check-row planter drawn by horses and deposit- 
 ing the seed at regular intervals so that the rows may be cultivated 
 with equal facility either in the direction of the planting or across. As a 
 means of cultivating the corn . . . the Jarmer quite commonly uses a 
 riding plow. Steam power corn-huskers and corn-shellers are found. 
 Instead of the old hand-method of shelling corn ... by which . . . 
 
 1 Report oj the Industrial Commission, vol. x., p. cxlix. 
 
The Demand for Labor in Agriculture 109 
 
 hardly six bushels could be shelled in a day, the farmer may now have 
 his corn shelled at the rate of a bushel a minute and the machine which 
 does the work will also "carry off the cobs to a pile or into a wagon, 
 and deliver the corn into sacks." Mowing machines, horse hay-rakes, 
 tedders, and stackers have revolutionized the work of making hay. It 
 formerly required eleven hours of man-labor to cut and cure a ton of 
 hay. Now the same work may be done in one hour and thirty 
 minutes. 
 
 ''The increased effectiveness of man-labor power when 
 aided by the use of machinery . . . varies from 150 per 
 cent in the case of rye to 2244 per cent in the case of bar- 
 ley." On the whole, the quantity of labor now requisite 
 for the production of the principal crop averages "a little 
 over one fifth of the quantity which would be requisite 
 under the former hand methods of cultivation. " Confining 
 the comparison to the period of the "new immigration," 
 "we shall find that the effectiveness of the average (agri- 
 cultural) worker in the United States was greater, by nearly 
 60 per cent, in 1900 than in 1880." 
 
 The quantity of labor saved by machinery in producing 
 the average crop of the last decade of the past century, as 
 compared with hand methods in use in the middle of the 
 century, is estimated by Professor Quaintance at 450,000,000 
 days. * The saving represents the labor of one and a half mil- 
 lion men working three hundred days in the year. This figure 
 suggests the reason why the new immigration does not go to 
 the farming sections of the United States. As the per capita 
 production of agricultural staples did not increase as fast 
 as the efficiency of agricultural implements and machinery, 
 there was an actual as well as a relative displacement of 
 labor. The same writer estimates the average quantity of 
 labor spent in producing the annual crops of the principal 
 cereals during the period from 1840 to 1870, at 173,000,000 
 work days, and the average number of work days used for 
 producing the annual crops of the period 1893-1896, at 
 120,000,000. There was accordingly an actual displace- 
 
 1 Quaintance, loc. cit., pp. 7. 8, 10, 18, 23, 30, 73. 
 
no Immigration and Labor 
 
 ment of 42 per cent of farm labor. x Since the number of 
 farmers had meantime increased, there must have been 
 an actual decrease in the number of hired farm hands. In 
 North Dakota a farmer who owns two quarter-sections of 
 land generally takes care of the farm himself, with his 
 family, until spring, and employs very little help during 
 his busy season. 2 As a rule, agricultural laborers are in 
 demand only during the harvesting season. 
 
 In consequence of limited demand, "agricultural labor is 
 . . . the least paid of all the great groups of occupations, even 
 allowing for the laborer's garden and other privileges." 3 
 Aside from the consensus of expert opinion, this fact is es- 
 tablished by statistical evidence for Kansas and California. 
 The former is predominantly agricultural, the latter indus- 
 trial, but the XIII. Census shows an increase of 71.2 per cent 
 in the value of implements and machinery since 1900, an 
 increase of 89.2 per cent in the value of live stock, and an in- 
 crease of 34.5 per cent in the rural population of California. 
 Judged by the increase in the value of buildings and ma- 
 chinery since 1900 both States are representative of the 
 average for the United States. 4 Their wage statistics may 
 therefore be accepted as typical (see Tables 14 and 15). 
 
 The hours of labor on the farms are longer than even in 
 the steel mills of Pennsylvania. In the Northwest and in 
 the South the general custom is to work from sunrise until 
 sunset; in Maryland the hours of labor in the dairying 
 business are generally from 4 or 5 o'clock in the morning to 
 7 or 8 o'clock at night, and about the same in other agri- 
 cultural pursuits. 5 It is true that the hours are so long 
 
 I Quaintance, loc. cit., pp. 32-33. 
 
 3 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. x., p. 846. More than one 
 half of the farms of North Dakota at the XII. Census were of a smaller 
 size. XII. Census, Agriculture, Part I., Table 4, pp. 30 et seq. 
 
 a Report of the Industrial Commission , vol . x . , pp . xx. See also Bulletin 
 of the Bureau of Labor, No. 72 (September, 1907), p. 406. 
 
 4 XIII. Census, vol. i, Population, p. 62, Table 39; vol. v., Agri- 
 culture, p. 79, Table 29. 
 
 6 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. x., pp. xx., cxix., cxx., cxxi. 
 The witness from Maryland testified that he "once heard a public 
 
The Demand for Labor in Agriculture in 
 
 TABLE 14. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS OF FARM LABORERS IN KANSAS, COMPARED 
 WITH EARNINGS IN SIMILAR NON-AGRICULTURAL OCCUPATIONS IN 
 THE SAME STATE, 
 
 
 Number 
 
 Average 
 annual 
 
 Average 
 number of 
 
 Average 
 number of 
 
 Occupation 
 
 reported 
 
 earnings 
 
 days 
 
 hours per 
 
 
 
 
 unemployed 
 
 day 
 
 Laborers: 
 
 
 
 
 
 On farms 
 
 35 
 
 $2Q6 a 
 
 ci 
 
 II. 6 
 
 In building trades. 
 
 19 
 
 323 
 
 93 
 
 9-3 
 
 On railroads 
 
 637 
 
 335 
 
 
 
 Coal miners 
 
 24 
 
 357 
 
 IIS 
 
 8-4 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TABLE 15. 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF WHITE MALE LABORERS, EMPLOYED IN AGRICULTURE 
 
 AND OTHER PURSUITS IN CALIFORNIA, BY RATES OF WAGES 
 PER WEEK (WITHOUT BOARD), 1906.3 
 
 
 Number reported 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Character of employment 
 
 $12.00 
 
 or 
 less 
 
 Over 
 
 $12.00 
 
 Total 
 
 $12.00 
 
 or 
 less 
 
 0-er 
 
 $12.00 
 
 Total 
 
 Agriculture 
 
 689 
 
 15 
 
 704 
 
 97-9 
 
 2.1 
 
 IOO 
 
 Stores and factories 
 
 2156 
 
 1964 
 
 4I2O 
 
 52.3 
 
 47-7 
 
 100 
 
 Lumber woods and saw mills 
 
 1610 
 
 3492 
 
 5102 
 
 3L6 
 
 68.4 
 
 IOO 
 
 Railway construction in and 
 around San Francisco . . . 
 
 556 
 
 1746 
 
 2302 
 
 24.2 
 
 75-8 
 
 IOO 
 
 speaker say that the farmers settled the eight-hour question by having 
 eight hours before dinner and eight after." 
 
 1 X VI. Annual Report of the Kansas Bureau of Labor, pp. 1 28-13 1 , 153, 
 
 2 Including the cost of board for ten months estimated at 90, given 
 in Table 2, p. 122. 
 
 3 Compiled from XII. Biennial Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics 
 of the State of California (1905-1906), pp. 7^-77. 80-161, 165. 
 
H2 Immigration and Labor 
 
 only in harvest and threshing time. After the rush i* 
 over the working day averages about ten hours. But at 
 that time very few laborers are retained on the farms. 
 
 Long hours, small pay, and irregular employment are what 
 the immigrant can expeet on a farm. His preference for 
 other employment seems to call for no explanation by 
 special racial characteristics; it is merely another illustra- 
 tion of the rule that immigration follows the demand for 
 labor. " In the settlement of agricultural districts a point 
 is reached beyond which any considerable growth of agri- 
 cultural population is possible only if there is a change to 
 more intensive forms of agriculture. ... If there is no 
 such change, the further growth of population must con- 
 sist in the development of urban or non-agricultural 
 communities." 1 
 
 This point has been reached in the United States. The 
 public domain has practically all passed into private occu- 
 pation. Land values during the last decade have climbed 
 to unheard-of heights. 2 At the same time Western Canada 
 offers to settlers vast areas of public land practically free. 
 
 1 XII. Census, Supplementary Analysis, p. 303. 
 
 * The highest average value per acre in 1900 was found for Illinois, 
 viz., $46. At the XIII. Census the following States exceeded that 
 maximum: 
 
 State Value per acre 
 
 California $47.00 
 
 New Jersey 48.00 
 
 Ohio 53.00 
 
 Indiana 62.00 
 
 Iowa 82.00 
 
 Illinois 95-00 
 
 The lowest average value in 1900 was in Wyoming, viz., $2.88; in 1910 
 the average value in that State reached $10.00 per acre. The lowest 
 average in 1910 was $8.77, computed for New Mexico. The average 
 value per acre for the United States doubled from 1900 to 1910, but 
 the maximum increase was as high as 475 per cent, viz., from $6.00 
 to $34.00 in Arizona. XIII. Census, vol. v., Agriculture, p. 80, Table 
 30. 
 
The Demand for Labor in Agriculture 113 
 
 It seems that for some time to come the Canadian North- 
 west will furnish the same opportunities for extensive agri- 
 culture as the Western States did a generation ago. Western 
 farmers find it profitable to dispose of their land in the 
 United States and to take up public land- in Western 
 Canada. x The emigration of American farmers to Canada 
 has reached considerable proportions. 2 In the United 
 States a market for agricultural labor may grow up in the 
 future with the eventual spread of intensive agriculture. 
 But this is a problem for the American farmer to solve. 
 The immigrant should not be burdened with the mission 
 to reform the methods of American agriculture. 
 
 1 The average value of land and buildings per farm in Iowa increased 
 from the XII. to the XIII. Census by more than $8000. Practically all 
 of this represented increased land value. "Canadian officials estimate 
 that in the fiscal year 1909 the United States emigrants brought to 
 Canada, in stock, cash, and effects, upwards of $60,000,000." (Reports 
 of the Immigration Commission, vol. 2, p. 616.) This is equivalent to 
 an average of $1000 per individual immigrant, or to $4000 per family. 
 
 * In 1910 the number of emigrants from the United States to Canada 
 reached 103,984. Ibid. 
 
CHAPTER VI 
 
 UNEMPLOYMENT 
 
 A. The Causes of Unemployment 
 
 AS far back as 1901 Prof. John R. Commons, in his 
 report on immigration prepared for the Industrial 
 Commission, reached the conclusion that immigrants come 
 to this country "in obedience to the opportunities for 
 employment. ' ' z Still the force of statistics must apparently 
 yield to the living proof, furnished by the ever-present 
 "army of the unemployed/' that there are already more 
 men than jobs in the United States. There seems to be no 
 escape from the conclusion that every new immigrant, in 
 order to live, must take away the job from some one else 
 who has been here before. 2 A study of the sources of un- 
 employment shows the fallacy of the premises upon which 
 the popular argument is based. 
 
 Unemployment in its present form is a problem peculiar 
 to our industrial system, but alternations of work and in- 
 voluntary idleness were incidents of the life on the old New 
 England farm as well. The disappearance of slavery in 
 New England was in no small degree due to the long winters 
 during which the time of the negro slave could not be fully 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 309. 
 
 3 "The popular conception is of industry as rigidly limited a sphere 
 of cast iron in which men struggle for living room; in which the greater 
 the room taken by any one man the less must there be for others; in 
 which the greater the number of men the worst must be the case of 
 all." W. H. Beveridge: Unemployment, a Problem of Industry, p. n. 
 
 114 
 
Unemployment 115 
 
 employed. The introduction of the factory system in New 
 England at the close of the eighteenth century was ad- 
 vocated on the ground that it would "give employment to a 
 great number of persons, especially females who now eat 
 the bread of idleness." 1 
 
 On the old farm, however, work and leisure were shared 
 by all members of the household and all were supported 
 by the work of the busy months. The differentiation of 
 lumbering, dairying, slaughtering, tool making, canning, 
 spinning, weaving, dressmaking, etc., from farming has 
 destroyed the former co-ordination of those occupations. 
 Nowadays, whenever work in any of them grows scarce, 
 some of the workers are cut off from the pay-roll and become 
 "unemployed." 
 
 The most generally recognized cause of unemployment is 
 seasonal variation of business activity. According to the 
 census of 1900, among masons and plasterers more than 
 one half were out of work a portion of the year. Next 
 follow brick- and tile-makers, of whom nearly one half 
 were at times unemployed. Among paper-hangers, the pro- 
 portion was 44 per cent; among carpenters and painters, 
 over 40 per cent; among fishermen, about one half; among 
 sailors, one third. All these occupations are dependent 
 upon the weather. Other trades are dependent upon and 
 decline with these. Then there are trades dependent 
 partly upon the weather and partly upon social customs; 
 more than one fourth (27 per cent) of all tailors were out 
 of work at some period during the year 1900. 2 In the 
 busiest season the supply of labor in such trades may often- 
 times be short of the demand, necessitating overtime work; 
 
 1 Helen L. Sumner: "History of Women in Industry in the United 
 States," Report on Condition of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in 
 United States, vol. ix., p. 43. See also pp. 38, 39. In the early years of 
 the nineteenth century the mills employed many farm girls who 
 were "not constantly at work, but as they had leisure from other house- 
 hold employment." Ibid., p. 47. See also Simons: Social Forces in 
 American History, p. 172 et seq. 
 
 * Occupations at the XII. Census, Tables LXXXVIL, and XC. 
 
n6 Immigration and Labor 
 
 yet even this shortage of labor will not save a portion of the 
 force engaged in such trades from idleness at other times 
 of the year. A reduction of the number of competitors for 
 positions in such trades would obviously not relieve the 
 situation. Masonry may serve as an example. Out of 
 every 1000 masons 555 were unemployed some time during 
 the census year 1900 and there was steady work all year 
 around for only 445. x Could the number of masons in the 
 United States have been reduced to the 445 who had steady 
 work in 1900, unemployment would thereby not have been 
 eliminated. On the contrary, many of the 445 who were 
 employed all year around when there were 555 more masons 
 in busy times would have lost part of their working time 
 with the exclusion of their competitors. The explanation 
 of this apparent paradox is that there is steady work on a 
 building for about one half of the total number employed 
 at the busiest time probably inside work which does not 
 depend upon the weather. But a building cannot be con- 
 structed all inside. If the number of masons were reduced 
 from looo to 500, the building operations at the busiest 
 season would necessarily have to be reduced one half, with 
 the result that during the slack season there would be only 
 enough inside work for 250 and the other 195 of the 445 
 who had steady work in 1900 would now go idle. The 
 same condition exists to a greater or lesser degree in many 
 other industries. 
 
 In order to eliminate unemployment it would be necessary 
 to dovetail the busy and the slack seasons in the various 
 industries upon such a plan as would produce an even dis- 
 tribution of the work of the nation over all seasons of the 
 year. This might be possible if all mines, mills, and trans- 
 portation lines were operated by one nation-wide combine, 
 ouch an adjustment of half a million independent business 
 establishments, however, is not feasible for more than one 
 ceason. In the first place, the periods of the highest and 
 lowest demand for labor are largly contemporaneous, in 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, p. ccxxxii., Table CX. 
 
Unemployment 117 
 
 all industries (see Diagram V). 1 The highest number 
 employed in manufactures, in the United States as a whole 
 as well as in every one of the principal States, is found in the 
 spring and in the fall, the lowest in winter. The workman 
 who is laid off in January has, as a rule, no opportunity 
 to secure other work. 
 
 In the second place, even when the slack period in one 
 industry coincides with the busiest period in another, the 
 mobility of labor is quite limited. The skilled trades admit 
 of no shifting from one occupation to another. May was 
 the busiest month of the year 1899 (see Diagram V). 
 In 51 industries an additional force of 400,000 men was 
 at work in excess of the permanent force employed at all 
 times of the year, including the slack season. On the other 
 hand, there were four industries for which May was the 
 dullest month, but the aggregate number laid off in those 
 industries was less than 7000. And yet with all that 
 demand for labor some of them must have remained out of 
 work. There were, e.g., 1924 idle jewelry workers. Help 
 was wanted in brick yards, 74,000 men; carpenter shops, 
 71,000; custom tailoring shops, 16,000; carriage and wagon 
 shops, 14,000; planing mills, 13,000; cigar factories, 6000.' 
 cheese factories, 5000, etc. There was not a single industry, 
 however, among the 51, which could furnish employment 
 to the 1924 idle jewelry workers. 2 Had every one of the 
 extra 400,000 men been deported to Europe, the 1924 idle 
 jewelers would nevertheless have remained unemployed. 
 Even if all the laborers in the brickyards were of un- 
 adulterated Puritan stock, a jewelry worker would consider 
 it beneath his social status to do rough work in a brickyard 
 while waiting for the resumption of work at Tiffany's. 
 The natural tendency is for the fact of seasonal fluctuation 
 to be recognized as a normal incident of the industry and 
 to be allowed for in the standard of wages. 
 
 The only class of labor whicfc is capable of shifting from 
 
 1 Based upon figures of XII. Census Report on Manufactures, vol. i, 
 Table 3, p. 62. * See Appendix, Table II. 
 
DIAGRAM V. 
 Scale for States: i unit = 10,000. For the United States: I unit = 100,000. 
 
 60 
 
 60 
 
 40 
 
 40 
 
 30 
 
 10 
 
 V. Average number of male wage-earners employed in manufactures 
 in the United States and the principal States, by months, 1899. 
 
 118 
 
Unemployment 119 
 
 one industry to another is unskilled labor. Yet the localiza- 
 tion of industries sets also a limit to the mobility of unskilled 
 labor. By way of illustration let us compare the iron and 
 steel and the lumber industry. Both employ large numbers 
 of unskilled laborers. The variation between the greatest 
 and the least number of men employed is over 200,000 in the 
 latter and only 80,000 in the former. Assuming that busy 
 and dull times dovetail in the -two industries, we shall 
 nevertheless find interchange of unskilled labor between 
 them restricted by geographical location. Nearly one half 
 of the iron and steel workers are employed in Pennsylvania; 
 there were 38,000 of them unemployed at one time or 
 another in 1899, whereas the highest number of extra men 
 hired during the same year in the lumber industry of the 
 same State was about 9000 ; more than three fourths of the 
 idle iron and steel workers of Pennsylvania could find no 
 employment in the lumber industry within their own 
 State. The same was true of Ohio, where there were at 
 one time or another 13,000 unemployed iron and steel 
 workers, while only 6300 temporary men found employ- 
 ment in the lumber industry within the same State. Men 
 were wanted in the lumber camps of Michigan, Wisconsin, 
 and Minnesota, 1 but the laborer who is employed on and 
 off in a steel mill around Pittsburgh will not take the risk 
 in the intervals to hunt for a temporary job in the lumber 
 camps of Minnesota. 
 
 The local and seasonal divergencies between the supply 
 of and the demand for labor have called into existence the 
 labor agent or the "padrone," whose business is that of a 
 broker in the labor market. To declaim against him is as 
 futile as to condemn the broker in the Produce Exchange. 
 The casual or " discontinuous" laborer in New York^City 
 has no means to learn that men are wanted by a railway 
 company in the West or South. The labor agent, who is in 
 communication with railway companies, building contrac- 
 tors, and other great employers of labor, renders a service 
 
 *XII. Census, Manufactures, Part I, Table 4, PP- 254-255. 286-291. 
 
120 Immigration and Labor 
 
 both to the employer and to the laborer. Being in business 
 for profit, he charges a commission for his services. That a 
 broker of this class is apt to take advantage of his client 
 does not mark him as an exception to the general run of 
 mankind in kindred occupations. It is a common error to 
 think that the labor agent is the specific product of Italian 
 or Greek immigration. We learn from the recent report 
 of Dr. Helen L. Sumner on the History of Women in Industry 
 in the United States that during the early years of the factory 
 system, before the era of immigration, the New England 
 factories "put forth systematic efforts to attract the farm- 
 ers' daughters of the surrounding country." A common 
 
 method of securing girls for the factories was to send out agents to the 
 country districts who were paid a stipulated sum per head for hiring 
 girls. As early as 1831 the Dedham (Mass.) Patriot announced that 
 " a valuable cargo, consisting of 50 females, was recently imported into 
 this State from ' Down East* by one of the Boston packets. . . ." The 
 Cabotville Chronicle spoke in 1864 of a " long, low, black, wagon" which 
 makes regular trips to the North of the State, cruising around in Ver- 
 mont and New Hampshire with a "commander" whose heart must be 
 as black as his craft, who is paid a dollar a head for all he brings to the 
 market, and more in proportion to the distance, if they bring them 
 from such a distance that they cannot easily get back. This is done 
 by "hoisting false colors," and representing to the girls that they can 
 tend more machinery than is possible and that the work is so very 
 neat, and the wages such that they can dress in silks and spend half 
 their time in reading. l 
 
 The abuses of unscrupulous labor agents must not blind 
 us, however, to the fact that they perform a necessary 
 social function, viz., that of distributing the labor supply 
 where it is wanted. The main shortcoming of this system 
 of distribution of labor is its inadequacy. The total number 
 of laborers shipped by all employment agencies out of New 
 York City to twenty-six States in more than two years 
 (May i, 1904, to July 31, 1906) was x>nly 40,737, a i.e., about 
 
 1 Report on Condition of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in the 
 United States, vol. ix., pp. 80-81 
 a Frank J. Sheridan: "Italian, Slavic, and Hungarian Unskilled Im- 
 
Unemployment 121 
 
 17,000 a year. The total number of laborers who were 
 unemployed at any time during the census year 1900 (the 
 latest for which data are available) was 40,108' and the 
 rate of unemployment in 1904-1906, as far as can be judged, 
 was about the same as in 1900.* It is safe to say that the 
 labor agencies were able to place outside of New York 
 City less than one half of all unemployed laborers. The 
 majority stayed in New York waiting for work "to pick up." 
 
 We come next to the cyclical fluctuations of business 
 which result in variations of the number employed from 
 year to year. A temporary decline in business means 
 unemployment for a number of wage-earners who were 
 employed the year before. Such fluctuations of business 
 occur in countries with a net emigration, like Great Britain, 
 or in France whose population is practically stationary, as 
 well as in the United States. The effect of these fluctua- 
 tions of business activity "is the requirement in each trade 
 of reserves of labor to meet the fluctuations of work inci- 
 dental to years of prosperity." 3 An illustration of the 
 range of these cyclical fluctuations is given in Diagram 
 VI. on p. 1 25.* 
 
 The most important cause of unemployment in point of 
 numbers affected, however, is to be found in the fact that 
 "the actual demand is that of each of many separate 
 employers in many different places." 5 The effect of this 
 "dissipation of the demand for labor in each trade" 6 upon 
 
 migrant Laborers in United States," Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, 
 No. 72, p. 417. 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table XLIII., p. 634. 
 
 a According to the statistics of the New York Bureau of Labor, the 
 ratio of unemployed in 1900 was 21.0 per cent; in 1904, 30.5 per cent; 
 in 1905, 14.6 per cent and in 1906, 8.6 per cent, averaging for 1904- 
 1906, 17.9 per cent. (Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 
 1908, p. xviii., Table 10.) While these figures relate to members of labor 
 unions only, they may serve as a standard of comparison of general 
 business conditions in various years. * Beveridge, loc. cit., p. 13- 
 
 Based on Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1910, 
 p. viii, s Beveridge, loc. cit., p. 10. 6 IM*., p. 13- 
 
122 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the mass of wage-earners can be measured by the difference 
 between the aggregate number of hands required by all 
 establishments at their busiest seasons and the aggregate 
 minimum number employed when business is at its lowest 
 ebb. To be sure, this difference does not represent the 
 amount of unemployment at any given date, since the 
 seasonal variations are not simultaneous in all industries 
 and a considerable portion of the unskilled laborers readily 
 shift from one industry to another. But every change of 
 position involves some period of unemployment, as it re- 
 quires some time to find a new job. This is clearly demon- 
 strated by the census statistics of manufactures. The 
 difference between the greatest and the least average 
 number employed during any month in the year is far short 
 of the difference between the aggregate greatest and the 
 aggregate least number employed in all establishments 
 during the same year, as shown in Table 16 next below: 
 
 TABLE 16. 
 
 RANGE OF FLUCTUATIONS OF EMPLOYMENT, 1899 AND 1904' 
 
 
 185 
 
 9 
 
 19 
 
 34 
 
 Number employed 
 (thousands) 
 
 Simultane- 
 ously, monthly 
 average 
 
 Aggregate in all 
 establishments 
 at any time 
 during the year 
 
 Simultane- 
 ously, monthly 
 average 
 
 Aggregate in all 
 establishments 
 at any time 
 during the year 
 
 
 67 
 
 7O6Q 
 
 5677 
 
 7OI7 
 
 Minimum . . 
 
 4.Q-J8 
 
 4.527 
 
 5262 
 
 4.CQQ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Difference 
 
 629 
 
 2545 
 
 415 
 
 2418 
 
 Percentage to 
 
 
 
 
 
 minimum. . 
 
 H 
 
 56 
 
 9 
 
 53 
 
 1 Compiled from XII. Census Report on Manufactures, Part I, p. 59, 
 Table 3; Genius Report on Manufactures, 1905, Part I, p. Ixxix., Table 
 XXVII. 
 
Unemployment 123 
 
 In order to ascertain the total number of wage-earners 
 who had steady employment during the year, the number 
 employed by each individual manufacturer on the slackest 
 day in his own business must be added to similar numbers 
 for all others, though the days may not have coincided. It 
 appears that this number was less than the lowest monthly 
 average, which means that even in the worst month of the 
 year more people are wanted on .an average than can be 
 given permanent employment. On the other hand, while 
 during the best month of the year 1899 only fourteen ad- 
 ditional wage-earners were needed over and above every 
 one hundred who had permanent employment, actually 
 four times as many persons were hired for temporary jobs 
 during the same year. In 1904, the proportion was still 
 more striking, the number of persons hired temporarily 
 was nearly six times greater than the actual temporary 
 force needed at the busiest time during the year. In either 
 year there were over one half as many temporary jobs as 
 permanent "positions. Of course, these figures comprise 
 many duplications ; there may have been few wage-earners 
 over the greatest number that could actually have been 
 employed at the same time; in that case each of the tem- 
 porary employees had about four different jobs during the 
 year 1899 and six during the year 1904. The unemploy- 
 ment intervening between one temporary job and another 
 clearly did not depend upon the number of applicants for 
 jobs, but was determined by the vicissitudes of business. 
 
 The whole problem of unemployment is admirably eluci- 
 dated in Mr. Beveridge's exhaustive treatise on the subject, 
 from which the following is condensed : 
 
 A general and normal excess of the supply of labor over the demand 
 appears to be explicable only by an excessively rapid increase of popula- 
 tion. But sucb an explanatior does not square with the facts showing 
 irreducible minimum of unemployment precisely in those industries 
 which have grown with exceptional rapidity in recent years. 
 
 The general formula for the supply of labor in an industry appears to 
 be this: for work requiring, if concentrated at one spot, at most ninety- 
 
124 Immigration and Labor 
 
 eight men, there will actually be eighty in regular employment; there 
 will be a hundred in all, so that at all times two at least are out of work. 
 The twenty, however, are as much part of the industrial system as are 
 the eighty ; the reserve is as indispensable as the regulars. The idleness, 
 now of some, now of others, of the reserve is mainly responsible for the 
 irreducible minimum of unemployment. The figures here given have 
 only an illustrative value; the proportion of regular and reserve and 
 irreducible minimum vary from trade to trade. The principle is of the 
 greatest generality. The rule for each trade is to have more men than 
 are called for together even at the busiest moment. 
 
 The normal state of every industry is to be overcrowded with labor, 
 in the sense of having drawn into it more men than can ever find em- 
 ployment in it at any one time. This is the direct consequence of the 
 work of each industry being distributed between many separate em- 
 ployees each subject to fluctuations of fortune. // depends upon the 
 nature of the demand for labor, not upon the volume of the whole supply. 
 
 To speak of the reserve of labor in a trade may become, in fact, only 
 another way of speaking of the whole volume of unemployment in it. 
 The change, however, is not one of words alone. It implies a revolu- 
 tion of mental attitude. It involves perception of unemployment, not 
 as a thing standing by itself an inexplicable excrescence on the indus- 
 trial system but as a thing directly related to that system and as 
 necessary to it as are capital and labor themselves. 
 
 Unemployment is not to bz identified as a problem of general over-popula- 
 tion. Unemployment arises because, while the supply of labor grows 
 steadily, the demand for labor, in growing, varies incessantly in volume, 
 distribution, and character. This variation in several of its forms at 
 least flows directly from the control of production by many competing 
 employers. It is obvious that, so long as the industrial world is split up 
 into separate groups of producers each group with a life of its own, and 
 growing or decaying in ceaseless attrition upon its neighbors there 
 must be insecurity of employment. Unemployment, in other words, 
 is to some extent at least part of the price of industrial competition 
 part of the waste without which there could be no competition at all. 
 
 B. Unemployment and Immigration 
 
 It has been shown that unemployment does not depend 
 upon the volume of the supply of labor, but is determined 
 by the nature of the demand for labor, which produces a 
 "relative surplus-population." Is itrnot possible, however 
 
 1 Beveridge, loc. cit. t pp. 70, 76, 99, 100, 103, 235. "A surplus labor- 
 ing population is ... a condition of existence of the capitalist mode of 
 
DIAGRAM VI. 
 
 Per cent, of employed and unemployed members of trade unions in the 
 State of New York, by months, 1902-1909. 
 
 production. . . . With accumulation, and the development of produc- 
 tiveness of labor that accompanies it, the power of sudden expansion 
 of capital grows also. . . . There must be the possibility of throwing 
 great masses of men suddenly on the decisive points without injury to 
 the scale of production in other spheres. . . . The whole form of the 
 movement of modern industry depends, therefore, upon the constant 
 transformation of a part of the laboring population into unemployed or 
 half-employed hands. . . . Taking them as a whole, the general move- 
 ments of wages are exclusively regulated by the expansion and con- 
 traction of the industrial reserve army. . . . They are, therefore, not 
 determined by the variations of the absolute number of the working 
 population, but by the varying proportions in which the working class 
 is divided into active and reserve army, by the increase or diminutirti 
 in the relative amount of the surplus population." Karl Marx, Capital, 
 part i., ch. xxv., sec. 3. 
 
126 Immigration and Labor 
 
 that the effects of ' 'the normal glutting of the labor market" x 
 may be aggravated by immigration? 
 
 It is asserted, indeed, on the strength of the investigation 
 of the Immigration Commission "that the point of complete 
 saturation has already been reached in the employment 
 of recent immigrants in mining and manufacturing estab- 
 lishments." 2 The Commission holds "that even with the 
 remarkable expansion of industry during the past few years 
 there has been created an oversupply of unskilled labor, 
 which "is reflected in a curtailed number of working 
 days." 3 
 
 It is further argued that the oversupply of unskilled labor 
 indirectly affects the skilled trades; more workers who 
 might otherwise find employment as unskilled laborers are 
 pushed up the scale to compete for skilled positions. This 
 is especially felt in slack seasons when skilled mechanics 
 would welcome any kind of work, even unskilled, which 
 would tide them over the hard times. But the oversupply 
 of unskilled labor restricts their opportunities in this field 
 and intensifies competition in the skilled trades. When two 
 competitors apply for one job in an overstocked labor 
 market, the cheaper man will outbid the other. It is 
 accordingly inevitable that the immigrant with a lower 
 standard of living must displace the American workman. 
 
 If this theory is correct, we must find a higher percentage 
 of unemployment among the native than among the foreign- 
 born breadwinners. In fact, however, we find the following 
 percentages of unemployment ascertained by the census for 
 
 > x Beveridge, loc. cit., p. 13. 
 
 * Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 197. 
 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , p. 39. The Com- 
 mission does not consistently adhere to this view. Elsewhere, in dis- 
 cussing the causes of the outward movement of immigrants leaving the 
 United States permanently, the Commission says: ''That it is not due 
 to lack of opportunity for employment, except in a period of depression, 
 is evident from the fact that there is a steady influx of European laborers 
 who have little or no difficulty in finding employment here." Ibid., 
 vol. 4 (in press). 
 
Unemployment 127 
 
 1 900: native white males, 21.2 per cent; foreign white males 
 21.0 per cent. 1 
 
 ^The difference between the two classes is negligible. 
 The figures do not sustain the theory that the immigrants 
 have an advantage over the native American workmen in 
 the matter of securing employment. Has the "cheap" 
 immigrant a better chance to hold his job, once secured, 
 than the native American workman? An answer to this 
 question is found in the following table reproduced from the 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, p. 87. 
 
 TABLE 17. 
 
 PER CENT, DISTRIBUTION OF NATIVE AND FOREIGN-BORN MALE IRON AND 
 STEEL WORKERS 1 6 YEARS OF AGE AND OVER BY NUMBER 
 OF MONTHS OF EMPLOYMENT 
 
 Number of months 
 employed 
 
 Native born 
 
 Foreign 
 born 
 
 Of native father 
 
 Of foreign father 
 
 9 and over 
 
 6O.2 
 234 
 13-5 
 2.9 
 
 50.2 
 28.3 
 I7.I 
 
 4.4 
 
 41.4 
 
 32.3 
 2O. I 
 6.2 
 
 6 and under 9 . . 
 
 and under 6 
 
 ess than 3 
 
 Total 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, p. ccxxvi. The census averages for 
 unemployment among female breadwinners are not reliable. The 
 highest ratios of unemployment were found among school teachers, 61.2 
 per cent, and in agricultural pursuits, 44.3 per cent, (p. ccxxxi), where- 
 as the ratio for manufactures was 22.4 per cent, for domestic and per- 
 sonal service, 17.1 per cent, and for trade and transportation, n.i per 
 cent (p. ccxxviii). The teachers' vacation was included by the compilers 
 of the census data under unemployment. Similarly, we find that in 
 most of the census talles on occupations female members of farmers' 
 families who were helping on the farm were lumped together with 
 hired help under the common designation of "agricultural laborers." 
 These "farm laborers (members of family) " numbered two thirds of all 
 "agricultural laborers" (ibid., p. 7). The part of the year when there 
 was no work for them on the farm was also counted as "unemployment." 
 
128 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The statistics of the Immigration Commission do not 
 show that the immigrant holds his position longer than the 
 American-born workman. On the contrary, in the iron 
 and steel industry, which is among those most affected by 
 immigration, the native workman is given more steady 
 employment than the immigrant. 
 
 If there exists a causal connection between immigration 
 and unemployment, we must expect to find more unemploy- 
 ment in those sections of the United States where the 
 immigrants are mostly concentrated. This assumption is 
 disproved by Table 18 next following: 
 
 TABLE 1 8. 
 
 COMPARATIVE PERCENTAGES OF UNEMPLOYED AND OF FOREIGN-BORN 
 BREADWINNERS BY GEOGRAPHICAL DIVISIONS, 
 
 ^Geographical divisions 
 
 Ratio of for- 
 eign white 
 to total num- 
 ber of bread- 
 winners 
 
 Ratio of breadwinners unemployed dur- 
 ing a portion of the year to total number 
 in each class and division 
 
 Manufacturing and 
 mechanical pursuits 
 
 Domestic and 
 personal service 
 (including la- 
 borers) 
 
 Continental United 
 States 
 
 19-7 
 2.9 
 
 37 
 23.5 
 277 
 31-5 
 
 27.2 
 25.2 
 28.6 
 
 29-5 
 
 28.1 
 
 25-7 
 
 28.1 
 28.1 
 31.0 
 30.7 
 28.6 
 
 24-3 
 
 South Atlantic. . . . 
 
 South Central 
 
 North Central 
 
 Western 
 
 North Atlantic . . . 
 
 
 As a result of this method of classification, the number of "unemployed " 
 female agricultural laborers (293,707) exceeded y nearly one third the 
 total number of hired female farm help (222,597). These two classes 
 of occupations furnished two fifths of all unemployed females (494,202 
 out of a total of 1,241,492), while the ratio of foreign-born was only 
 5.3 per cent for teachers and 0.8 per cent for agricultural laborers 
 (ibid., pp. 10-11, Table 2). In consequence the average percentage of 
 " unemployment " for native white women in all occupations appears to 
 be higher than for foreign -born. It is evident that the census data on 
 unemploy ent among women are misleading, which is conceded in the 
 census report. 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table XCIIL, pp. Ixxxi., ccxxxv., 
 and ccxxxvi., Tables XVII. and XCIII. 
 
Unemployment 129 
 
 A glance at the table shows that the percentage of un- 
 employment is not affected by the percentage of foreign- 
 born engaged in the main classes of occupations. The 
 variation of the ratio of unemployment from section to 
 section is confined within narrow limits. The ratio of un- 
 employment in manufactures is the same for the South 
 Atlantic and the North Atlantic States, though there are 
 very few foreign-born in the South Atlantic States, while 
 in the North Atlantic States they constitute nearly one 
 third of all operatives. In all other sections of the country 
 the ratio of unemployment is slightly higher than in the 
 North Atlantic States, while the percentage of foreign-born 
 breadwinners engaged in manufactures is less, and in the 
 South Central States much less than in the North Atlan- 
 tic States. The same is true of the miscellaneous collection 
 of occupations lumped together in census statistics under 
 the head of "domestic and personal service," which in- 
 cludes unskilled laborers. We find the lowest ratio of un- 
 employment in the North Atlantic States, with 31.5 per 
 cent of foreign-born breadwinners and the highest in the 
 South Central States, with but 3.7 per cent of foreign-born 
 breadwinners. 
 
 Comparative statistics showing the ratio of unemploy- 
 ment and the percentage of foreign-born breadwinners by 
 sex and by States are available for the manufacturing 
 industries at the XII. Census. The measure of unemploy- 
 ment, for the purposes of this comparison, is the difference 
 between the total greatest and the total least monthly 
 average number employed, expressed as a percentage of 
 the greatest monthly average. The data for manufactures 
 relate to the calendar year 1899 and the distribution of 
 breadwinners by nativity is for the summer of 1900. The 
 dates are sufficiently close to make the figures comparable. 1 
 
 There is considerable variation of the ratio of unemploy- 
 ment, as well as of that of foreign-born, by States. There 
 are some States with a high percentage of foreign-born and 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table III. 
 
130 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 low ratio of unemployment and vice versa; there are others 
 with high percentages both of foreign-born and of un- 
 employment and vice versa. The ratio of unemployment 
 seems sometimes to rise and sometimes to fall with the 
 percentages of foreign-born. But a significant correla- 
 tion between the two ratios is disclosed if all States 
 are combined into two areas according to the ratio of 
 foreign-born engaged in manufactures and mechanical 
 pursuits : 
 
 I. Those States where the ratio of foreign-born in 
 manufactures is below the average for the United States; 
 
 II. Those States where that ratio is above the average 
 for the United States. 
 
 The statistics relating to each area are summarized 
 separately for male and female wage-earners in Tables 19 
 and 20. 
 
 TABLE 19. ' 
 
 GREATEST AND LEAST NUMBER OF MALE WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED IN 
 MANUFACTURES DURING ANY ONE MONTH OF THE YEAR 1899, 
 GREATEST NUMBER OF UNEMPLOYED, AND PERCENTAGE OF FOREIGN- 
 BORN MALES ENGAGED IN MANUFACTURES AND MECHANICAL 
 PURSUITS IN 1900, BY GROUPS OF STATES. 
 
 States with percentage 
 of foreign-born in 
 manufactures and 
 mechanical pursuits 
 
 Employed in 
 manufactures 
 (thousands) 
 
 Unemployed 
 sometime 
 
 Per cent ratio of foreign- 
 born to all males in 
 manufactures and me- 
 chanical pursuits. 
 
 Least 
 number 
 
 Great- 
 est 
 number 
 
 Thou- 
 sands 
 
 Percent of 
 greatest 
 number 
 employed 
 
 Least 
 
 Greatest 
 
 Below the average. . 
 Above the average. . 
 
 1224 
 2524 
 
 1501 
 2907 
 
 277 
 
 383 
 
 18.5 
 13-2 
 
 I.O 
 
 33-2 
 
 31-9 
 53-8 
 
 Total 
 
 3748 
 
 4408 
 
 660 
 
 ^5-o 
 
 Average 
 32.7 
 
 
Unemployment 
 
 TABLE 20. 
 
 GREATEST AND LEAST NUMBER OF FEMALE WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED IN 
 MANUFACTURES DURING ANY ONE MONTH OF THE YEAR 1899, GREAT- 
 EST NUMBER OF UNEMPLOYED, AND PERCENTAGE OF FOREIGN-BORN 
 FEMALES ENGAGED IN MANUFACTURES AND MECHANICAL PURSUITS, 
 IN IQOO, BY GROUPS OF STATES. 
 
 
 Employed in 
 manufactures 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Per cent ratio of foreign- 
 born to all females in 
 
 States with percentage 
 of foreign-born in 
 
 (thousands) 
 
 sometime 
 
 manufactures and me- 
 chanical pursuits 
 
 manufactures and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 mechanical pursuits 
 
 Least 
 number 
 
 Great- 
 est 
 number 
 
 Thou- 
 sands 
 
 Per cent of 
 greatest 
 number 
 
 Least 
 
 Greatest 
 
 
 
 
 
 employed 
 
 
 
 Below the average. . 
 
 352 
 
 442 
 
 90 
 
 20.4 
 
 0.2 
 
 20.3 
 
 Above the average. . 
 
 573 
 
 668 
 
 95 
 
 14.2 
 
 22.7 
 
 46.2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Average 
 
 Total 
 
 925 
 
 IIIO 
 
 185 
 
 I6. 4 
 
 21.4 
 
 
 Combining all the States where the immigrants furnish 
 from one third to more than one half of all males engaged in 
 manufactures and mechanical pursuits, we find that the 
 ratio of unemployment in that area as a whole is lower than 
 in the other area, where the immigrants are few in numbers, 
 rising in no State to one third of all males employed in 
 manufacturing industries and falling as low as i per cent. 
 The same rule holds true with regard to female wage-earners 
 employed in manufactures. On the whole, unemployment is 
 in inverse ratio to the relative number of foreign-born. 
 
 The underlying cause of this relation will be apparent, 
 if we remember that the number of foreign-born wage- 
 earners is regulated by immigration and emigration and 
 that both movements promptly respond to changes in the 
 business situation. (See Chapter IV.) 
 
 Still the variation of the ratio of unemployment by States 
 may be affected by the localization of industries; certain 
 industries concentrated in a State with a small foreign-born 
 population may through climatic or other causes be more 
 subject to ebb and flow than other industries located in a 
 
132 Immigration and Labor 
 
 State with a large immigrant population. The ratio of 
 unemployment must therefore be compared for different 
 occupations with a varying percentage of foreign-born 
 breadwinners. 
 
 Diagram VII furnishes the data for a comparative study 
 of fifty leading occupations which gave employment, in 
 1900, to seven and a half million male breadwinners. 1 
 
 If it be true that unemployment is intensified by immi- 
 gration, the aggregations of solid black bars representing 
 unemployment and striped bars representing the percentage 
 of foreign-born male breadwinners in each occupation 
 should be expected to display some similarity in outline. 
 No such tendency is suggested by the diagram ; the variation 
 of the ratio of unemployment for different occupations 
 shows no effects of immigration. 
 
 Although the number of occupations selected for compari- 
 son, as well as the number of persons engaged in them, is 
 very large and well distributed over all sections of the 
 country, yet, in order to eliminate the possible effect of 
 localization of industries, we shall next compare the varia- 
 tions of the ratios of unemployment and of the percentage of 
 foreign-born within the same occupations by States. Space 
 forbids an exhaustive treatment of all the leading occupa- 
 tions shown in Diagram VII. Our study will be confined to 
 three occupation groups: bituminous coal-miners, common 
 laborers, and cotton-mill operatives. The first two have 
 been selected in view of the popular belief, accepted by the 
 Immigration Commission, that they are suffering from an 
 oversupply of unskilled immigrant labor. The cotton-mill 
 operatives, on the other hand, afford the opportunity to 
 contrast the New England mills, where the majority of the 
 workers are of foreign birth, with the Southern mills 
 dependent almost exclusively upon native labor. 
 
 Diagram VIII presents in graphic form the ratio of un- 
 
 1 The comparative figures for these occupations, as well as for the 
 leading occupations of female breadwinners are given in the Appendix, 
 Table IV. 
 
DIAGRAM VII 
 
 D"~ H 
 
 J EinfUTttO AU. re/W BY. FoRiton WHrtt 
 
 VII. Per cent unemployed at any time during the year and per 
 cent of foreign-bora in fifty leading occupations, 1900. 
 
 T33 
 
134 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 employment in bituminous coal-mining collated with the 
 
 percentage of foreign-born miners. The former ratio has 
 
 DIAGRAM VIII 
 
 Percentage Foreign -bom 
 Ratio of Unemployment 
 VH1. Ratio of unemployment in bituminous 
 coal mines, 1902, and percentage of 
 foreign-born miners, 1900. 
 
 been computed by the method applied above to manu- 
 factures. The greatest and the least number of wage- 
 earners are taken from the census report on Mines and 
 
Unemployment 135 
 
 Quarries for 1902, while the percentage of foreign-born is 
 that for 1900, but the dates are sufficiently near for compara- 
 tive purposes. 1 As the statistics of occupations by States 
 do not distinguish coal miners from other miners and 
 quarrymen, the comparison is confined to those States where 
 coal mining was practically the only mining industry. 2 
 The diagram includes, however, all principal coal-mining 
 States in 1902 which produced 83 per cent of the total 
 coal output of the United States. 3 No connection between 
 unemployment and immigration is disclosed by the diagram. 
 Pennsylvania, which holds the third highest place according 
 to the percentage of foreign-born miners, stands next to the 
 State with the lowest ratio of unemployment. The highest 
 ratio of unemployment is found in West Virginia, where 
 the percentage of foreign-born miners is next to the lowest 
 
 Similar variations by States appear in the statistics 
 relating to the other two occupations selected for compari- 
 son. To further trace the interdependence, if any, 
 between immigration and unemployment in these occupa- 
 tions, we shall again combine all States into two areas, 
 first, according to the percentage of foreign-born ; and next, 
 in the same manner, according to the ratio of unemploy- 
 ment. The results of these combinations are summarized in 
 Tables 21 and 22. 4 
 
 An examination of Table 21 shows that the percentage 
 of unemployment is slightly less in the area where the 
 immigrants furnish 44 per cent of all common labor, than 
 in the rest of the United States where the foreign-born 
 laborers constitute one tenth of the total number. The 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table V. 
 
 3 In Pennsylvania a large number of coal miners were employed in the 
 anthracite mines; the latter, however, were affected by the strike of 1902 
 and could for this reason not be included in a comparison between the 
 greatest and the least number employed. But the employment of 
 immigrants is general in both classes of mines. 
 
 * Mines and Quarries, p. 680. 
 
 < Detailed statistical data for each State will be found in the Appendix 
 Tables VI. and VII. 
 
136 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 21. 
 
 LABORERS (MALE), FOREIGN-BORN AND UNEMPLOYED, IQOO. 
 
 Areas 
 
 Total 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Number 
 
 Per 
 cent 
 
 Number 
 
 Per 
 
 cent 
 
 With percentage of 
 foreign-born: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Above the average . . . 
 Below the average . . . 
 
 1,317,218 
 1,188,029 
 
 580,682 
 122,853 
 
 44.1 
 10.3 
 
 570,401 
 539,324 
 
 43-3 
 454 
 
 With percentage of 
 unemployed: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Above the average . . . 
 Below the average . . . 
 
 1,031,548 
 1,473.699 
 
 252,453 
 451 ,082 
 
 24.4 
 30.6 
 
 498,881 
 610,844 
 
 484 
 41.5 
 
 Total 
 
 2,505,247 
 
 703,535 
 
 28.1 
 
 1,109,725 
 
 44-3 
 
 
 TABLE 22. 
 
 COTTON-MILL OPERATIVES (MALE), FOREIGN-BORN AND UNEMPLOYED, 
 
 1900. 
 
 Areas 
 
 Total 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Number 
 
 Per 
 
 cent 
 
 Number 
 
 Per 
 
 cent 
 
 With percentage of 
 foreign-born: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Above the average . . . 
 Below the average . . . 
 
 65,984 
 59,031 
 
 46,009 
 1,982 
 
 69.7 
 
 34 
 
 7,725 
 8,551 
 
 11.7 
 14-5 
 
 Total 
 
 125,015 
 
 47.991 
 
 384 
 
 16,276 
 
 13-0 
 
 With percentage of 
 unemployed: 1 
 
 Above the average . . . 
 Below the average . . . 
 
 52,882 
 7L7I9 
 
 10,479 
 37499 
 
 19.8 
 52-3 
 
 8,380 
 7,842 
 
 15.6 
 9-1 
 
 Total 
 
 124,601 
 
 47,978 
 
 38-5 
 
 16,222 
 
 13-0 
 
 
 1 Exclusive of Kentucky where the percentage of unemployed is 
 equal to the average. 
 
Unemployment 137 
 
 difference is negligible. Evidently conditions of employ- 
 ment of unskilled laborers are everywhere such that well- 
 nigh one half of them, whether native or foreign-born, have 
 no steady work and lose a part of their time during the year 
 in changing from one situation to another. If the arrange- 
 ment of the States is reversed and they are grouped into 
 two areas according to whether the percentage of unemploy- 
 ment is above or below the average for the United States 
 as a whole, it appears that in the area with the higher ratio 
 of unemployment the percentage of foreign-born laborers 
 is lower. 
 
 The same relation is disclosed by Table 22 with regard to 
 male cotton-mill operatives. In the area with 70 per cent 
 of foreign-born operatives the percentage of unemployed 
 is slightly less than in the area where 96 per cent of all 
 operatives are of native birth. Reversing the arrangement 
 we find again that in the area with the higher ratio of 
 unemployment only one fifth of all operative are foreign- 
 born, whereas, in the area with the lower ratio of unemploy- 
 ment over one half of the operative force are immigrants. 
 In other words, immigrants, as a rule, are not attracted to 
 the cotton mills of those States where opportunities for 
 steady employment are less favorable. 
 
 The preceding analysis justifies the conclusion that there 
 is no causal connection between unemployment and immi- 
 gration, the ratio of unemployment within the same occupa- 
 tion being substantially the same in areas with a large 
 immigrant population and with practically none at all. 
 
 The preceding conclusions have been derived from an 
 inquiry into the conditions of employment for one census 
 year. We shall next examine whether there is any connec- 
 tion between immigration and unemployment compared 
 for a series of years. The Massachusetts Bureau of Labor 
 Statistics has collected annual statistics of the greatest and 
 the least number of wage-earners employed in factories 
 since the middle of the 8o's. Table 23 shows the variation 
 of the ratio of unemployment for twenty years from 1888 
 
138 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 to 1908. The standard of comparison is the same as before, 
 viz., the difference between the greatest and the least 
 number employed. 1 
 
 TABLE 23. 
 
 RATIO OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN MASSACHUSETTS, 1888-1908* 
 
 Year 
 
 Percent 
 
 Year 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Year 
 
 Per cent 
 
 1888 
 
 23 
 
 1895 
 
 26 
 
 1902 
 
 23 
 
 1889 
 
 23 
 
 I8 9 6 
 
 33 
 
 1903 
 
 25 
 
 1890 
 
 22 
 
 1897 
 
 28 
 
 1904 
 
 26 
 
 1891 
 
 22 
 
 1898 
 
 30 
 
 1905 
 
 23 
 
 1892 
 
 23 
 
 1899 
 
 26 
 
 1906 
 
 29 
 
 1893 
 
 36 
 
 I90O 
 
 27 
 
 1907 
 
 25 
 
 1894 
 
 33 
 
 1901 
 
 25 
 
 1908 
 
 33 
 
 The years 1893, 1894, an d I 9 8 show the effects of indus- 
 trial crises, and the year 1896 those of the unsettled business 
 situation produced by the free silver agitation. With 
 those exceptions the variation of the ratio of unemployment 
 from year to year is small. The ratio is lower for the seven 
 years of the present century characterized by heavy immi- 
 gration than for the preceding decade when immigration 
 was small. The relation between unemployment and 
 immigration is shown graphically in Diagram IX. 3 It is 
 clearly seen that with increasing immigration unemploy- 
 
 1 The returns are not complete, especially for the earlier years; a 
 comparison of the numbers employed would therefore be misleading. 
 Nevertheless, the numbers reported are so large that the percentage of 
 unemployment could not be materially varied by the addition of the 
 missing figures. The inquiries of the Bureau call for the number em- 
 ployed during the current and the preceding year. As a result the 
 figures for the previous year published in every annual report are more 
 complete than those published the year before. A comparison of the 
 percentage of unemployment for each year computed from the numbers 
 published in two consecutive reports shows that the variations do not 
 exceed a fraction of I per cent. In Table 23 fractions of i per cent 
 have been omitted. a See Appendix, Table VIII. 
 
 3 See Appendix, Table IX. 
 
Unemployment 
 
 139 
 
 ment decreases, and with declining-immigration unemploy- 
 ment increases. The tendency disclosed by this diagram 
 DIAGRAM IX 
 
 00 
 
 <r 
 
 IX. Ratio of unemployment of factory workers in Massachusetts 
 
 and number of immigrant breadwinners destined for 
 
 Massachusetts, 1897-1908. 
 
 is but a corroboration of the rule that immigration follows 
 the demand for labor. The condition in Massachusetts, 
 
140 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 which is a manufacturing State with a large immigrant 
 population, may be accepted as typical. 
 
 Heretofore we have dealt with unemployment as ex- 
 pressed in the relative number of wage-earners unem- 
 ployed during any portion of the year, regardless of the 
 duration of employment. It is maintained, however, by 
 the Immigration Commission, that the effects of immi- 
 gration are reflected in a " curtailed number of working 
 days" per wage-earner. The report of the Commission 
 contains no statistical data in support of this assertion. 
 There are, however, official figures on this subject for tho 
 two principal States affected by immigration, New York 
 and Pennsylvania. Table 24 shows the number of days 
 worked in the bituminous coal mines of Pennsylvania dur- 
 ing the calendar years 1901-1909, the average tonnage 
 mined per day per man, along with the number of immigrant 
 miners and laborers bound for Pennsylvania during the 
 fiscal years 1901-1909. In Diagram X the same data are 
 represented graphically. 
 
 TABLE 24. 
 
 AVERAGE NUMBER OF DAYS WORKED IN BITUMINOUS COAL MINES OF 
 PENNSYLVANIA, AVERAGE PRODUCTION PER EMPLOYEE PER DAl 
 WORKED, AND NUMBER OF IMMIGRANT MINERS AND LABORERS 
 (INCLUDING FARM LABORERS) DESTINED FOR PENNSYLVANIA, 
 1901-1 909. * 
 
 Year 
 
 Immigrants 
 (fiscal years) 
 
 Days 
 (calendar years) 
 
 Tons per day 
 (calendar yean) 
 
 1901 
 
 63,713 
 
 216 
 
 3-5 
 
 1902 
 
 95.967 
 
 221 
 
 3-6 
 
 1903 
 1904 
 
 II4,Ol8 
 78,625 
 
 216 
 190 
 
 It 
 
 1905 
 
 127,417 
 
 216 
 
 3-6 
 
 1906 
 
 116,923 
 
 239 
 
 3-4 
 
 1907 
 
 141,830 
 
 238 
 
 
 1908 
 
 54.813 
 
 I8 4 
 
 3-6 
 
 1909 
 
 69,291 
 
 2IO 
 
 3-7 
 
 1 Reports of the Commissioner of Immigration, 1901, Table VII. ; 1902- 
 
CALENDAR YEARS 
 
 DIAGRAM X. 
 
 340 
 330 
 
 220 
 2ZO 
 20O 
 190 
 1 80 
 
 ISO 
 
 NUMBE K OF 
 
 100 
 
 IMMIGRANT MINERS AND LA&OR&& 
 mr/tfYlVWM 
 
 i ! ] I ri i 
 
 5C/M. YEARS 
 
 Average number of days worked in the bituminous coal mines 
 of Pennsylvania and number of immigrant miners and 
 
 laborers destined for Pennsylvania, 1901-1909 
 Scale for immigrants: i unit = 1000 
 
142 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The average number of days the mines were worked might 
 not be identical with the average number of days of em- 
 ployment for each mine worker. But the average tonnage 
 mined per day worked serves as a measure of the amount of 
 work furnished every miner per day. The average for the 
 nine- year period is a little over three and a half tons per 
 employee per day, the fluctuations from year to year are 
 insignificant. The number of days in operation accordingly 
 represents the number of days of employment. It can be 
 seen from Diagram X. that the curves representing immigra- 
 tion and days of employment run almost parallel. The 
 deviations from that course are slight, and one of them can 
 be accounted for by temporary conditions unrelated to 
 immigration. The increase of the average number of days 
 worked in 1902 was due to the anthracite coal strike, which 
 increased the demand for bituminous coal. In 1903, after 
 the settlement of the strike, the number of days worked 
 again dropped to the level of 1901. Of course, no mathe- 
 matical accuracy must be expected from these curves. 
 On the one hand, the number of immigrant laborers com- 
 prises a great many who found employment in other indus- 
 tries than bituminous coal mines; on the other, the number 
 of days is not a weighted average and has only the value of 
 an approximation. On the whole, however, the tendency 
 of the two curves is unmistakable; the number of days 
 of employment rises and falls as immigration rises and 
 falls. 
 
 The statistics of the New York Labor Bureau are col- 
 lected annually through correspondence with officers of labor 
 unions and show the number of days of employment in 
 organized trades. While these statistics relate primarily 
 to the skilled crafts only, yet indirectly they reflect the 
 conditions in the industrial field as a whole. Nowadays 
 there are few skilled crafts that^o not enter as a part into 
 a larger industrial system. Unemployment of the engineer 
 
 1908, Table IX; 1909, p. 57. Reports of the Department of Mines of 
 Pennsylvania, Part II., for the years 1901 to 1909. 
 
Unemployment 143 
 
 or fireman means unemployment for a number of factory 
 hands. 
 
 In Diagram XI. days of employment are plotted along 
 with the number of immigrants, exclusive of dependents, 1 
 who gave New York as their destination on landing. 2 
 The two upper curves represent the average number of 
 days of employment during the first and the third quarter 
 of every year from 1897 to 1909,* the lowest heavy line 
 represents immigration of breadwinners. Contrary to the 
 general assumption, the rise of the immigration curve is not 
 followed by a decline of the curves representing duration of 
 employment. On the whole, the three curves move in a 
 uniform direction ; the number of days of work increases as 
 immigration increases, and declines as immigration declines. 
 In the fall of 1900 (a presidential year), there was less work 
 on an average than in the fall of 1899, but the middle curve 
 shows that conditions improved in the spring of 1901. 
 These fluctuations were reflected in the total immigration 
 for the fiscal year ended June 30, 1901, which remained 
 almost stationary. A divergence between the employment 
 and immigration curves strikes the eye in 1907. The 
 spring of that year was marked by a decline of employment 
 compared with the preceding year, and the opportunities 
 in the fall showed no progress compared with the previous 
 fall, whereas the immigration curve was still rising. The 
 effects of the curtailment of the days of employment were 
 reflected in the immigration curve next year. On the other 
 hand immigration continued to decline when the condition 
 of the labor market began to improve. The conclusion 
 that can be drawn from this divergence is that it takes some 
 time before the conditions of the labor market are reflected 
 in the immigration movement. As stated in a preceding 
 
 *"No occupation (mostly women and children)," in Immigration 
 Bureau terminology. 
 
 3 For detailed figures see Appendix, Table XXIII. 
 
 3 Annual Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1909, 
 vol. ii, p. xvii., Table 5. 
 
Days 
 
 2 g 
 
 cn <o 
 
 \ 
 
 
 %\ 
 
 \ 
 
 2 
 
 \ 
 
 i 
 
 \ 
 
 \ 
 
 in 
 
 to 
 
 trv 
 *o. 
 
 144 
 
Unemployment 145 
 
 chapter, the arrivals of immigrants in the United States 
 at any given time are the result of preparations made some 
 months before their embarkation on the other side. Viewed 
 as a whole, however, the diagram strongly contradicts the 
 assumption that immigration results in the curtailment of 
 the days of employment. During the ten normal years 
 1897-1906, which preceded the crisis of 1907, the number of 
 working days increased with the increase of immigration. 
 It could not have been a fortuitous coincidence. No one 
 claims that the arrival of the immigrants was the cause of 
 the increase of the per capita share of work. By the method 
 of exclusion there is room for no other inference than that 
 immigration has merely responded to the increased demand 
 for labor. 
 
 The preceding analysis may be summed up in the follow- 
 ing proposition: 
 
 Unemployment and immigration are the effects of 
 economic forces working in opposite directions; that which 
 produces business expansion reduces unemployment and 
 attracts immigration; that which produces business de- 
 pression increases unemployment and reduces immigration. 
 
 Yet it may be said that while immigration is not a con- 
 tributory cause of unemployment, restriction of immigra- 
 tion would nevertheless reduce unemployment. An answer 
 to this argument is furnished by the example of Australia, 
 where immigration does not keep up with emigration, and 
 yet unemployment is an ever-present problem, precisely as 
 in the United States. Australia is a new country with 
 abundant natural resources. Its area is as great as that 
 of the continental United States (exclusive of Alaska), 
 while its population at the census of 1906 was a million 
 short of the United States figure for 1800. The Austral- 
 ian statistics of unemployment essentially differ from ours. 
 The XII. Census counted all breadwinners who were idle at 
 any time during the twelve months preceding the date of 
 enumeration. The statistics of the New York Bureau of La- 
 bor comprise all wage-earners who were unemployed during 
 
146 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the first or the third quarter of the year. The Australian 
 statistics, on the other hand, give the number unemployed 
 on the date of enumeration. A comparison of the Austra- 
 lian ratio of unemployment with the New York ratio must 
 therefore be favorable to Australia and unfavorable to New 
 York. Still the comparison is highly instructive. The 
 Australian ratio in 1901 varied from 3.96 per cent for 
 South Australia to 6.73 per cent for New South Wales. 1 
 In the State of New York the total amount of unemploy- 
 ment for the three summer months, July, August, and Sep- 
 tember, fluctuated during the years 1897-1907 between 
 1.9 per cent and 6.5 per cent. 2 It thus appears that 
 Australia with an excess of emigration over immigration is 
 suffering from unemployment at least as much as the State 
 of New York, which is teeming with immigrants. It is 
 evident that unemployment is created by the modern 
 organization of industry even in the absence of all 
 immigration. 
 
 Unemployment not being the result of overpopulation, it 
 necessarily follows that limitation of the number of wage- 
 earners can promise no relief against unemployment. To 
 be effective, any proposed remedy must attack the problem 
 of unemployment, not collaterally, through restriction of 
 immigration, but directly. 
 
 A radical remedy for the evils of unemployment is offered 
 by the Code of Labor Laws of the Russian Soviet Govern- 
 ment. The law assures to every able-bodied citizen ' ' the right 
 to employment*' at his trade or vocation at the standard 
 wage fixed for such class of work. The Government, through 
 its employment service, undertakes to find a job for every 
 unemployed worker. Every person who is out of work may 
 register at the local office of the Division of Distribution of 
 Labor Power. All establishments in need of workers may 
 
 Victor S. Clark: "Labor Conditions in Australia," Bulletin of the 
 Bureau of Labor, No. 56 p. 180. 
 
 * Annual Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1909, vol. 
 ii., p. xvii., Table 5. 
 
Unemployment 147 
 
 likewise register with the local government employment office 
 their demand for labor, stating the qualifications of workers 
 and the kind of work required, as well as the terms of em- 
 ployment. The local office assigns the applicants in the 
 order of their registration. In case the local supply of work- 
 ers is insufficient to meet the demand for a certain class of 
 workers, the local employment office communicates with 
 other offices within the same region. If the supply of labor 
 of a certain class is in excess of the demand, the applicant 
 for work may be temporarily offered a job outside of his 
 trade. An applicant for whom no employment can be found 
 is entitled to draw a benefit, equal to his standard wages, 
 out of an unemployment insurance fund levied on all em- 
 ployers of labor, including government institutions. When- 
 ever a worker is directed to a position below his grade of 
 work, he is entitled to draw upon the unemployment insur- 
 ance fund for the difference between his standard rate of 
 wages and that actually offered to him. 1 
 
 1 Code of Labor Laws. Compilation of the Statutes and Orders of the 
 Labor and Farmer Government, December 10, 1918, Sections 10, 20-23, 
 26, 28-30, and Supp. to Sec. 79, 6, 7, 14, 15. A summary of that 
 Code appears in the Monthly Labor Review of the U. S. Dept. of Labor, 
 April, 1920, pp. 210-214. 
 
CHAPTER VII 
 
 RACIAL STRATIFICATION 
 
 I NDUSTRIAL evolution has broken down the stable or- 
 1 ganization of ancient and mediaeval societies, in which 
 every individual had a fixed place and the son followed 
 the occupation of the father. Modern industrial society 
 tends to revert to the nomadic type. People come and go, 
 and others settle in their places. There were, in 1900, 
 thirteen and a half million persons born in the United States 
 who were living outside of their native States. There is 
 no record of migration within State limits. Assuming that 
 the number of native citizens migrating within their State 
 of birth is equal to the number migrating to contiguous 
 States, six millions more may be added to the migratory 
 population, making in all about 30 per cent of the total 
 native population. 1 Yet when it is learned that of the 
 2,653,000 native Missourians who were living in the United 
 States, 618,000 resided outside of their native State, while 
 855,000 natives of other States settled in Missouri, 2 no one 
 takes it that the Missourians were "displaced" by the 
 "invasion" of a host nearly a million strong from Southern 
 and Eastern States. It is only when the new-comers are 
 of foreign birth that the impression of "racial displace- 
 ment" is created. 
 
 There was one great racial displacement in America : the 
 Indian was displaced from his land by the European in. 
 vasion. The invasion and the displacement in that instance 
 
 *XII. Census, Supplementary Analysis, p. 281. 
 *Ibid., Table 61, pp. 850 et seq. 
 
 148 
 
Racial Stratification 149 
 
 were physical acts, not metaphors. When the term "racial 
 displacement" is applied to immigration, it suggests the 
 idea of a virtual crowding out of the native American by the 
 alien invader. 1 No doubt, in the shifting of population 
 from East to West, from country to city, the racial composi- 
 tion of many settlements has changed. Within the memory 
 of the present generation the Irish and German colonies of 
 New York City gradually moved out of the sections they 
 had occupied in the 8o's and early 90*3 of the past century 
 and in their places Jewish and Italian colonies grew up. 
 Still the old Irish or German settler of ten or twenty years 
 ago can be located in another section of the great city, and 
 the public is conscious of the fact that he has simply moved 
 from one neighborhood to another which seemed to him 
 more attractive. The population of New York City, 
 however, is large enough to fill several States. Were the 
 same population spread over a hundred cities of about 
 forty thousand inhabitants each and had the German resi- 
 dents of one city gradually moved out of it to others within 
 a radius of twenty-five miles, their places being filled by a 
 new race, the change would be keenly felt by many. The 
 grocer, the butcher, the hotelkeeper, the physician, the 
 lawyer, would be losing patronage. In their minds the 
 change would be reflected as the "displacement" of the old 
 
 'The definition of the word "displacement" given by the Oxford 
 English Dictionary is as follows: 
 
 Displacement: The act of displacing or fact of being displaced. Re- 
 moval of a thing by substitution of something else in its place. 1880, 
 Library Universal Knowledge: "The displacement of human labor 
 through machinery." 
 
 Hydrostatics: The displacing of a liquid by a body immersed in or 
 floating on it. 
 
 Displace: 
 
 1 . To remove or shift from its place; to put out of the usual place. 
 
 2. To remove from a position, dignity, or office. 
 
 3. To oust (something) from its place and occupy it instead. . . . 
 
 (fc) to take the place of, supplant, replace. A. R. Wallace, 
 "Darwinism"; "This weed . . . absolutely displaced every 
 other plant on the ground." 
 
150 Immigration and Labor 
 
 settlers by the new-comers. And yet the element of crowd- 
 ing out, even in a metaphorical sense, might be wholly 
 absent. The abandonment of the New England farms may 
 serve as an illustration. No one "displaced" the New 
 England farmer ; the population of many a town fell off, but 
 few new settlers, native or foreign-born, came to take the 
 places of those who had gone. The old homesteads were 
 left to decay and their proprietors went West, where they 
 found better opportunities. And now we witness the same 
 movement in Iowa, whose population has decreased since 
 1900, the farmers being attracted by cheaper lands in 
 Western Canada. 
 
 Is it not possible that a similar process has been going on 
 in manufacturing, in mining, in railroading? Where there 
 was a wilderness thirty years ago, several new States with a 
 substantial population have grown up. The railroads of 
 the West needed employees, who had to come from the East. 
 From 1879 to 1909, the manufactures of New England and 
 the Middle Atlantic States added one and a half million 
 wage-earners to their personnel, whereas the industrial 
 development of the rest of the country created opportunities 
 for two and one third million new hands, as shown in Table 
 25 next below. The manufactures in the West and South 
 grew much faster than in the East and drew some of the 
 native workers and earlier immigrants from the older manu- 
 facturing States. Still the demand for labor in those 
 States also grew. The places left vacant by the old 
 employees who had gone westward had to be filled by 
 new immigrants. The term "displacement" would be 
 misapplied to such a migration of wage-earners, as 
 much as in the case of the migration of the New England 
 farmer. 
 
 Let us see what light can be thrown upon this question 
 by the statistics of occupations. According to the figures 
 of the XII. Census, covering the~whole area of the United 
 States, the economic stratification within the principal 
 
Racial Stratification 
 
 elements of the white population in 1900 exhibited very 
 characteristic differences, as appears from Table 26. 
 
 TABLE 25. 
 
 AVERAGE NUMBER OF WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED IN MANUFACTURES 
 (THOUSANDS), 1879-1909.1 
 
 
 
 
 ] 
 
 ncrease 
 
 Geographic divisions 
 
 1879 
 
 1909 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 New England and Middle Atlan- 
 tic States 
 
 1700 
 
 -I-7QQ 
 
 TCTQ 
 
 8* 
 
 All other States 
 
 QAO 
 
 11O6 
 
 2-766 
 
 o 
 
 OC2 
 
 
 
 OO*-"- 1 
 
 
 o-* 
 
 Total, United States. ... 
 
 2710 
 
 6615 
 
 188 <; 
 
 Id.2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TABLE 26. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF MALE BREADWINNERS 21 YEARS OF 
 AGE AND OVER, BY NATIVITY AND CLASS OF OCCUPATIONS, 
 
 
 Nativ< 
 
 ; white 
 
 T 
 
 
 Native 
 parents 
 
 Foreign 
 parents 
 
 white 
 
 Industrial wage-earners 
 
 27.6 
 
 4O.8 
 
 52.8 
 
 Business 3 and professional pursuits, com- 
 mercial and clerical employment 
 
 57 7 
 
 4.-I.Q 
 
 ^5.5 
 
 All others 
 
 14. 7 
 
 1C. 7 
 
 II. 7 
 
 
 
 
 
 The majority of Americans of native parentage, in 1900, 
 were engaged in farming, in business, in the professions, 
 and in all sorts of commercial and clerical pursuits. The 
 majority of the immigrants, on the other hand, were indus- 
 trial wage-earners. 4 
 
 The question is, was t-his adjustment of native and 
 foreign elements on the scale of occupations attended by 
 actual " racial displacement"? Comparing the numbers 
 
 1 XII. Census, vol. vii., pp, clxxii-clxxiii. XIII. Census, Manu- 
 factures, vol. viii., p. 542. 
 
 3 Isaac A. Hourwich, "The Social-Economic Classes of the Population 
 of the United States." The Journal of Political Economy, April, 191 1 , p. 
 227. 3 Including farming. 
 
 4 Speaking of the immigrants in a "representative" coal-mining 
 community (Shenandoah, Pa.), the Immigration Commission states 
 
152 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of persons engaged in each occupation at the censuses of 
 1900 and 1890, we find a decrease of native breadwinners 
 in the following occupations : 
 
 TABLE 27. 
 
 OCCUPATIONS IN WHICH THE NUMBER OF NATIVE-BORN DECREASED, 
 1 890- 1 900. l 
 
 Native-born of native parentage. Decrease 
 
 Male: (Thousands) 
 
 Carpenters and Joiners 25 
 
 Boot- and shoe-makers and repairers 12 
 
 Woodworkers, including cabinet makers and coopers . . 7 
 
 Masons 6 
 
 Boatmen, canalmen, pilots, and sailors 3 
 
 Dairymen 2 
 
 Brick and tile makers I 
 
 Tailors I 
 
 All others 19 
 
 Total 76 
 
 Female: 
 
 Seamstresses 9 
 
 Tailoresses I 
 
 Textile mill operatives 2 
 
 Dairywomen I 
 
 Total 13 
 
 Both sexes 89 
 
 Native-born of foreign parentage. 
 Male: 
 
 Brick and tile makers I 
 
 Dairymen I 
 
 All others I. 
 
 Total 3 
 
 Female: 
 
 Cotton mill operatives I 
 
 Tailoresses i_ 
 
 Total 2_ 
 
 Both sexes 5^ 
 
 GRAND TOTAL 94 
 
 that they "have done practically nothing in the way of initiating new 
 industries. ... A few small candy and cigar factories and blacksmith 
 shops have been established by foreigners, but these are insignificant in 
 number and size." (Reports, vol. 16, p-655.) All schools of political 
 economy agree that "initiating new industries" is the function of 
 capital. But the majority of the foreigners are wage-earners. 
 1 See Appendix, Table X. 
 
Racial Stratification 
 
 153 
 
 In all, from 1890 to 1900, 94,000 native breadwinners 
 dropped out of the occupations enumerated in the preceding 
 table. If we were to assume that this figure represents 
 actual displacement (which it does not, as will presently be 
 shown), it would amount to only 2.5 per cent of the total 
 immigration for the decade 1890-1900. At the same time 
 the increase of native white of native parentage in all occu- 
 pations, exclusive of farming, exceeded two and a half 
 millions. It means that there were twenty-five other 
 opportunities for every position given up by the native 
 breadwinners of the above enumerated classes. 
 
 The figure 94,000 must not be mistaken, however, for 
 the number of individuals discharged from their former 
 positions. In the first place, an allowance must be made for 
 decrease by death. Taking those occupations which are 
 specified in the statistics of mortality at the XII. Census, we 
 obtain the following comparative ratios: 
 
 TABLE 28. 
 
 DECREASE FROM ALL CAUSES, COMPARED WITH LOSS BY DEATH AMONG 
 
 NATIVE WHITE MALES OF NATIVE PARENTAGE, IN SELECTED 
 
 OCCUPATIONS, I890-I900. x 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Number 
 engaged 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Per cent of total for each occupation 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 Decrease 
 
 Loss 
 by 
 death 
 
 Net accessions ( +) 
 or 
 defections(-) 
 
 Masons 
 
 65 
 
 37 
 
 354 
 15 
 
 71 
 
 59 
 34 
 
 329 
 14 
 
 59 
 
 - 9-2 
 - 8.1 
 
 - 7-1 
 - 6.7 
 
 16.9 
 
 -19.9 
 -18.8 
 
 -17-2 
 -II. 8 
 
 - 9-4 
 
 + 10.7 
 + 10.7 
 
 4-10. 1 
 + 5-1 
 
 - 7-5 
 
 Boatmen, canalmen, 
 pilots, and sailors. 
 Carpenters and 
 joiners . 
 
 Tailors 
 
 Boot- and shoe- 
 makers and re- 
 pairers 
 
 1 XII. Census, Vital Statistics, vol. i., p. ccix. Occupations at the 
 XII. Census, Table 2. Compendium of the XI. Census, Part III: Popu- 
 lation, Table 78. 
 
154 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The decrease of the number of native white males of 
 native parentage in all but the last occupation included in 
 the preceding table is accordingly accounted for by the 
 fact that the new accessions from that class were insufficient 
 to fill the places of those who died. 
 
 On the other hand, an actual decrease of the number of 
 American workmen of native stock was found among shoe- 
 makers and repairers. On closer scrutiny, however, it 
 appears that this decrease was merely a part of a general 
 decline of the trade, which manifested itself in a decrease of 
 the number of foreign-born shoemakers as well. Among 
 other occupations of the same class were brick and tile 
 makers, whose total number was reduced by 10,000, and 
 dairymen whose number was reduced by 8000; more than 
 one half of those reductions affected foreign-born workers 
 (7000 in the former and 4000 in the latter occupation). 
 The same is true of the other occupations specified in Table 
 27. As far as can be judged from census figures, there was 
 consequently no "displacement" of native by foreign 
 workmen. 
 
 Coming to female wage-earners, we find that while there 
 was a decrease of 13,000 American women of native stock 
 and of 2000 native of immigrant parentage employed as 
 seamstresses, tailoresses, textile mill operatives, and dairy- 
 women, the number of servants and waitresses showed a 
 decrease of 41,000 foreign-born, contemporaneous with an 
 increase of 16,000 white American girls of native stock 
 and 47,000 native daughters of immigrants. It may be in- 
 ferred from these figures that the women of the "new im- 
 migration " showed a tendency to prefer factory work to 
 domestic service, while the tendency among native American 
 girls was in the opposite direction. x 
 
 1 Most of the female factory workers_being young, the decrease by 
 mortality may be disregarded. On the other hand, however, "women 
 enter industry only temporarily. The census shows that the great 
 majority of them who are at work are between 16 and 30 years of age 
 that is, they are in industry until they get married. " (Nearing : Wages 
 
Racial Stratification 155 
 
 On the whole, the number of native women of native 
 parentage in gainful occupations increased by more than 
 half a million, as against a possible displacement of 13,000; 
 in other words, for every native woman of native paren- 
 tage who left the mill or clothing factory there were forty 
 women of the same nativity who found new openings. 
 The increase of the number of professional women of 
 that class was 63,000, i. e., nearly five times as great as 
 the decrease of the number of native American factory 
 girls. The loss of the 2000 positions by native women of 
 foreign parentage was compensated by an increase, of 
 
 348,000 in the number of the same nativity employed in all 
 
 J orfsro fenoifiboB 
 occupations. .p ; 
 
 It is evident from these figures that the "displacement," 
 if there was any, was negligible, and. moreover that it did 
 not manifest itself in those occupations which are believed 
 to be affected by immigration. The three occupations 
 
 mostly spoken of in connectioii witn / ^racial dfeplace- 
 
 , , , . , , . Sum 2l9"iodl fUoq-fmi'/ioT io 
 
 ment viz., laborers, miners, and iron and steel work- 
 
 1 t_ 't ' i; ' J .'. ' '' i r '2- 
 
 ers, show increasing numbefs^pja^e ^or^en of nafovj 
 
 paren age. iO^oab Ijrm;tri oifl io'l cm OvLwn 
 
 Unskilled laborers appear in census statistics under, TWO 
 designations : ' ' agricultural ^laborers, "^nd" laborers , not 
 specified." At the census of .1890, many farm laborers in 
 agricultural districts were reported sirnplv^a^^^lgQqr^ijs^^ 
 while at the census of 1900 tjbje djs^c|ip r n^between these two 
 classes was more strictly drawn. In consequence, the in- 
 crease of the number of non-agricultural laborers, appearing 
 from the census returns for f i^p^ J; is below ^e.aptfjai^figui^. 
 The increase of the number .of non-agricultural laborers iden- 
 
 tified as such and d^^f^y&f^ ^4l!o^ 
 Table 29 next below : 
 
 .qq ,s olduT ,iuim 
 
 -- .8? jIJoT iKC -'-I .aft oUflT . JI 
 
 *. the United States, 
 
 number of women of every nativity engaged in a given occupation would 
 accordingly be greatly reduced by marriage, unless there were Others of 
 the same class to fill their'places. " ^ < y or? . qq ^, , .^r 
 
156 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 29. 
 
 INCREASE OF THE NUMBER OF LABORERS IN THE UNITED STATES, 
 CLASSIFIED BY RACE AND NATIVITY, 1890-1900. * 
 
 . Race and Nativity (Thousands). 
 
 Native white 458 
 
 Native father 333 
 
 Foreign father 125 
 
 Foreign-born 41 
 
 Colored 158 
 
 Total... 657 
 
 It appears from Table 29 that only 6 per cent of the 
 additional demand for unskilled labor was supplied by 
 immigrants. Since the percentage of foreign-born among 
 agricultural laborers is much smaller than among other 
 unskilled laborers, 2 the underestimate of the numerical 
 increase of the foreign-born in the latter class is smaller 
 than for the occupation in general ; the percentage of increase 
 of foreign-born laborers must accordingly be rather over- 
 estimated than underestimated. In other words, immigra- 
 tion during the decade 1890-1900 was barely sufficient to 
 make up for the natural decrease of unskilled laborers by 
 death. 
 
 Yet the totals for the country at large might conceal 
 local displacements of considerable magnitude. Turning 
 to the State figures for 1890 and 1900 we find a decrease of 
 the number of native white laborers of native parentage 
 in the following States: Colorado, 1000 men; Delaware, 
 100 men; Utah, 100 men; and Rhode Island, 300 men. 3 
 But in the first three States the number of foreign-born 
 laborers likewise decreased. The total "displacement" of 
 native white laborers of native parentage by immigrants 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 2, pp. 10 and 1 1. XI. Census, 
 Population, Part II., Table 82, p. 354; Table 78, p. 304. 
 
 a The ratio of foreign-born in 1900 was_5.8 per cent among agricul- 
 tural laborers and 27.1 per cent among "laborers not specified." 
 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 2, pp. 10 and II. 
 
 * Ibid., Table 41, pp. 220-423. XI. Census, Population, Part II., 
 Table 116, pp. 530-627. 
 
Racial Stratification 157 
 
 was thus represented by a decrease of 300 men in the Sta,te 
 of Rhode Island, or by thirty men annually. It is within 
 the range of possibility that those thirty men may have 
 crossed the State line to Massachusetts or Connecticut, 
 the first of which, shows an increase of 2100 and the second 
 an increase of 1400 native white laborers of native parent- 
 age. No decrease of the number of common laborers 
 among the native white of native parentage appears in any 
 of the great States which serve as centres of attraction for 
 immigration. The native white of foreign parentage show 
 an increase during the same period in every State and 
 territory. 
 
 What has been said of laborers is equally applic- 
 able to miners, as can be seen from Table 30, two 
 thirds of the increased demand for miners having been 
 supplied by native-born workmen and only one third by 
 immigrants. 
 
 ^TABLE 30. 
 
 INCREASE OF TEE NUMBER OF MINERS IN THE UNITED STATES, 
 CLASSIFIED BY NATIVITY (THOUSANDS), 1890-1900. x 
 
 Native white 108 
 
 Native parents 73 
 
 Foreign parents 35 
 
 Colored 13 
 
 Foreign-born 61 
 
 Total 182 
 
 Comparing the number of miners by States in 1890 and 
 1900, we find a decrease in the employment of native white 
 miners only in the following States 2 : 
 
 XL Census, Population, Part II., p. 304. Table 78, and pp. 354 and 
 355, Table 82. Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 2, pp. 12 and 13. 
 
 XI. Census, Population, Part II., Table 116, pp. 540, 564. 5^2, 54. 
 594, 608, and 616. Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 41, pp. 242, 
 294, 332, 334. 358. 386 and 400. 
 
158 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 31. 
 
 DECREASE OF THE NUMBER OF NATIVE WHITE MINERS, 
 BY STATES. 
 
 Maine 200 
 
 New Hampshire 100 
 
 Vermont 200 
 
 Connecticut 200 
 
 North and South Dakota. 100 
 
 Nevada 500 
 
 Total 1300 
 
 The total loss of 1300 positions by native miners would 
 have been amply compensated by the employment of 70,000 
 American miners of native stock in excess of the number 
 employed at the preceding census. In fact, however, not 
 all of this decrease represents "racial displacement." In 
 Connecticut, Maine, and Nevada, it was due to a general 
 decline of the mining and quarrying industry, which affected 
 all employees, native as well as foreign-born. The actual 
 "displacement" was confined to 400 men in New Hampshire, 
 Vermont, and the Dakotas, without any allowance for 
 decrease by death. Non^oJ^tl^se States was affected oy 
 the ' ' new immigration, ' ' Such States as Pennsylvania and 
 Illinois, on the other hand, showed large increases in the 
 number of native miners, both of foreign arid bt native 
 parentage. ^noi^q ovituVl 
 
 The Statistics of iron and steel workers ci^ssMe^y race 
 and nativity appear in Table 32. The fundamMtal fact 
 brought out by the table is the differerice K iri ri tfie ) 'rate of 
 industrial expansion between the two last decades of the 
 past century; while in 1880-1890 the increase in the number 
 oljsm&fo^ 
 
 period 1890-1900 the demand for labor doubled. The 
 effect of this difference' is s'deri iri'ffie'faH'tha't dnriiig'the 
 first period, when tfte. jnumber of immigrants from Southern 
 
 DIIS -wLf. .ny T>n.LL,8T oicffiT ,|.Of .q-JI.-tV' * .woiUuM^oH..^^!** 1 ^. AY i 
 and Eastern Europe was negligible^ only 12,000 additional 
 
 American workmen found employment in thearon and steel 
 industry, or one man to every six who had been employed 
 in 1880; during the period 1890-1900, on -the: other hand, 
 
Racial Stratification 159 
 
 when immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe began 
 to come in, the number of native employees of every nativity 
 more than doubled. For every one additional American 
 workman engaged in 1880-1890, eight new American work- 
 men were added to the labor forces in 1890-1900, and there 
 was still room for immigrants. 
 
 TABLE 32. 
 
 NUMBER OF IRON AND STEEL WORKERS IN THE UNITED STATES, BY 
 RACE AND NATIVITY (THOUSANDS), l88o, 1890, AND 
 
 
 
 
 
 lucres 
 
 se 
 
 Race and Natirity 
 
 1880 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 1880-1890 
 
 1890-1900 
 
 Native-born, total 
 
 7-7 
 
 8^ 
 
 184 
 
 12 
 
 
 White, total 
 
 n 
 
 70 
 
 172 
 
 
 yy 
 
 Q1 
 
 Native parents . . . 
 
 (*> 
 
 4.C 
 
 Q4, 
 
 12 
 
 yo 
 
 AQ 
 
 
 W 
 
 -14. 
 
 78 
 
 
 Vy 
 
 AA. 
 
 Colored 
 
 (*) 
 
 6 
 
 12 
 
 
 6 
 
 Foreign-born, total 
 
 4.2 
 
 c8 
 
 lO'l 
 
 1*6 
 
 AC 
 
 Eastern and Southern 
 Europe . 
 
 
 
 
 24. 
 
 
 21 
 
 All other countries 
 
 42 
 
 55 
 
 79 
 
 13 
 
 24 
 
 Grand total 
 
 lie 
 
 14.1 
 
 287 
 
 28 
 
 Id.4. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 (*) Not reported. 
 
 As stated above, an increase of the total number of native 
 workmen in the United States does not preclude the possi- 
 bility of local displacements of native workmen by immi- 
 grants. As an actual fact, however, no evidence of such 
 displacements can be discovered by a comparison of the 
 distribution of iron and steel workers by States in 1890 and 
 1900. In two States only the census returns for 1900 
 showed a decrease of native white iron and steel workers 
 since 1890, viz., in Montana 100 men, and Nebraska 300 
 men; total, 400 men. Neither of these States holds an 
 important place in the iron and steel industry. Both 
 
 1 Compiled from the Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, 
 pp. 21-22, Tables 14 and 15, and vol. I, pp. 784, 785, Table 4. 
 
i6o 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 States show a general decline of the number of iron and 
 steel workers from 1890 to 1900, viz., Montana from 600 to 
 300 and Nebraska from 1000 to 500. This decline affected 
 foreign-born as well as native workers. Alabama alone 
 shows a displacement of the majority of colored iron and 
 steel workers (1300 out of a total of 1700) by immigrants. 
 But while the aggregate decrease of the number of native 
 white and colored workers through racial displacement and 
 other causes did not exceed 1700 men in three States, the 
 total increase of the number of native-born iron and steel 
 workers in the United States was as high as 99,000, dis- 
 tributed over all important iron- and steel-producing 
 States. 1 
 
 We may go one step further, following the lead of the 
 Immigration Commission into four of the principal centers 
 of the iron and steel industry, but we shall look in vain for 
 evidence of "racial displacement." The results of the 
 comparison are presented in Table 33. 
 
 TABLE 33. 
 
 INCREASE OF THE NUMBER OF IRON AND STEEL WORKERS IN THE PRIN- 
 CIPAL CITIES OF THE MIDDLE WEST BY RACE AND NATIVITY, 
 
 City 
 
 Native-born 
 
 Foreign 
 white 
 
 Grand 
 total 
 
 White 
 
 Colored 
 
 Total 
 
 Native 
 parents 
 
 Foreign 
 parents 
 
 Chicago, Illinois. . . 
 Milwaukee, Wis- 
 
 404 
 
 110 
 222 
 
 83 
 
 1522 
 
 1002 
 1031 
 152 
 
 3707 
 
 21 
 I 
 
 39 
 I 
 
 1947 
 
 III3 
 1292 
 236 
 
 1166 
 
 1324 
 2377 
 249 
 
 6113 
 
 2437 
 3669 
 
 485 
 
 Cleveland,Ohio... 
 Toledo, Ohio 
 
 Total for the 4 
 cities 
 
 SlQ 
 
 62 
 
 4588 
 
 8116 
 
 12,704 
 
 
 1 XII. Census, Occupations, Table 41, pp. 220-423; XI. Census, 
 Population, Part II., pp. 530-627. 
 
 a Computed from Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, 
 p. 9, Tables 559 and 560. 
 
Racial Stratification 161 
 
 In every one of the four cities chosen for comparison by 
 the Commission we find an actual increase in the number of 
 native workers of native and foreign parentage, white and 
 colored. Of course, this fact does not mean that every 
 individual worker of old American stock who had been 
 employed in the iron and steel mills of Chicago or Cleveland 
 in 1 890 was holding his old place in 1900. Some surely have 
 left the mills and gone to other occupations, while their 
 particular places may have been filled by immigrants, 
 which gives occasion to old-timers to speak in a reminiscent 
 mood of "racial displacement." But the scientific inves- 
 tigator must look beyond individual life stories to the 
 movements of population as reflected in great numbers. 
 The effect of immigration upon the distribution of the 
 native- and foreign-born labor forces is shown in Table 34 
 next following, compiled from material collected by the 
 Immigration Commission. 
 
 " In this table skilled laborers are arbitrarily considered 
 to be those who are receiving more than $1.45 per day 
 (i4j/ cents per hour), and unskilled laborers those receiv- 
 ing $1.45 or less per day. The classification is made upon 
 the basis of the wage-scale of the steel company, which 
 provides for a maximum payment of $1.45 for a day of ten 
 hours to unskilled or common laborers." 
 
 The effect of immigration upon the distribution of the 
 labor forces in the iron and steel industry is apparent from 
 the following table; all but one tenth of the native and 
 Northern and Western European workmen have been 
 shifted to skilled occupations, while nine tenths of all 
 unskilled positions have been filled by new immigrants 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe. "The change is 
 sometimes described as a forcing out of the American and 
 Americanized foreign employees. That is hardly accurate, 
 however," says the Immigration Commission, "for the 
 
162 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 34. 
 
 NUMBER AND PER CENT OF SKILLED AND UNSKILLED LABORERS IN ONE 
 IRON AND STEEL CONCERN, 1907. r 
 
 Nationality 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent of total for 
 each national group 
 
 Total 
 
 Skilled 
 
 Unskilled 
 
 Skilled 
 
 Unskilled 
 
 Native white: 
 Foreign- born: 
 From Northern 
 and Western 
 Europe 
 
 5257 
 
 27 
 31 
 
 4 
 
 $ 
 
 841 
 
 38 
 731 
 2434 
 1371 
 1391 
 964 
 
 3471 
 6929 
 
 4678 
 
 27 
 30 
 
 55 
 1530 
 395 
 346 
 743 
 
 9 l 
 
 280 
 126 
 84 
 5 
 
 3126 
 598 
 
 579 
 
 
 
 i 
 4 
 157 
 45 
 
 
 
 63 3 5 
 
 2154 
 1245 
 1307 
 
 959 
 
 345 
 6331 
 
 89.0 
 1 00.0 
 
 96.8 
 
 93-2 
 90.7 
 89.8 
 89.6 
 
 88.3 
 
 18.4 
 i3-i 
 II-5 
 9.2 
 6.0 
 5 
 
 90.1 
 8.6 
 
 II.O 
 
 o.o 
 
 i:I 
 
 9-3 
 
 IO.2 
 IO.4 
 II.7 
 
 81.6 
 86.9 
 88.5 
 90.8 
 94.0 
 95-5 
 
 9-9 
 91.4 
 
 Scotch. . . 
 
 
 Swedish 
 
 
 Welsh 
 
 English 
 
 Irish 
 
 From Southern 
 and Eastern 
 Europe: 
 Bohemian. . . . 
 Magyar 
 
 Slovak 
 
 Polish 
 
 Croatian 
 Italian. 
 
 Recapitulation: 
 From Northern 
 and Western 
 Europe 
 
 From Southern 
 and Eastern 
 Europe 
 
 Total white... 
 
 15,657 
 
 8402 
 
 7253 
 
 53-8 
 
 46.2 
 
 1 Compiled from the Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, 
 p. 350, Table 252. 
 
Racial Stratification 163 
 
 immigrant does not appear to underbid the American, or at 
 the present time to be even competing with him in any 
 serious way for the better-paid positions. " x In reality, the 
 "racial displacement" has manifested itself in that 
 
 a part of the earlier employees who remained in the industries in which 
 they were employed before the advent of the Southern and Eastern 
 European, have been able, because of the demand growing out of the 
 general industrial expansion, to rise to more skilled and responsible 
 executive and technical positions which required employees of training 
 and experience . . . 
 
 The same tendency asserts itself in the distribution of employees 
 according to race in bituminous coal mines, where all occupations of a 
 higher grade are filled by native Americans or older immigrants and 
 their children, while the Southern and Eastern Europeans are confined 
 to pick mining and unskilled and common labor. The same situation 
 exists in other branches of manufacturing enterprise. 3 
 
 This racial distribution of the operating forces has 
 developed a deep social tendency which constitutes the 
 main distinction between American and European labor 
 conditions. It is pretty generally accepted by European 
 economists, nowadays, that concentration of industry has 
 reduced the ratio of proprietors to wage-earners and thereby 
 diminished the probability of a wage-earner working his 
 way up to the status of a proprietor; at the same time the 
 introduction of machinery has reduced the relative number 
 of skilled mechanics to a minority of the operating force, 
 leaving to the mass of unskilled laborers few opportunities 
 for advancement on the scale of occupations. As a result, 
 the average European laborer has come to regard his place 
 in the industrial system as fixed. Such has not been the 
 attitude of the American wage-earner. Though the intro- 
 duction of machinery has had the tendency in the United 
 States, as in Europe, to reduce the relative number of 
 skilled mechanics, yet the rapid pace of industrial expansion 
 has increased the number of skilled and supervisory positions 
 
 r Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, p. 583. 
 3 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 195, 196. 
 
164 Immigration and Labor 
 
 so fast that all but "the thriftless, unprogressive elements 
 of the original operating forces " * have had the opportunity 
 to advance on the scale of occupations. The few examples 
 of "captains of industry" who have risen from the ranks of 
 labor will inspire only the most optimistic. But the 
 presence of great numbers of commonplace American work- 
 men who started at the bottom and have advanced to better 
 paid positions in the mills has kept up in the average 
 American wage-earner the ambition to rise individually. 
 A good illustration of these tendencies is furnished by the 
 statistics of the iron and steel industry. Of the 15,657 white 
 iron and steel workers employed in all plants of Industrial 
 Concern No. I in 1907, about one half were American and 
 Americanized skilled men. (See Table 34 above.) Looking 
 back to the time before the advent of the immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, we shall find that the oppor- 
 tunity for all of the original operating forces to advance to 
 skilled positions was conditioned upon the concern doubling 
 its force within the period of working efficiency of one 
 generation. It has been shown that the total number 
 employed in the iron and steel industry of the United States 
 doubled from 1890 to 1900. It is easy to calculate what 
 the opportunities of the "English-speaking" 2 wage-earners 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. tit., p. 194. 
 
 3 The Immigration Commission has adopted the race classification 
 popularly used in mill towns and mining camps. This classification is 
 thus explained by Mr. Fitch: "By the Eastern European immigration 
 the labor force has been cleft horizontally into two great divisions. 
 The upper stratum includes what is known in mill parlance as the 
 'English-speaking men'; the lower contains the 'Hunkies' or 'Ginnies.' 
 Or, if you prefer, the former are the 'white men,' the latter the 'for- 
 eigners.' An 'English-speaking' man may be neither native Ameri- 
 can, nor English, nor Irish. He may be one of these, or he may be 
 German, Scandinavian, or Dutch. It is sufficient if the land of his 
 birth be somewhere west of the Russian^ Empire or north of Austria- 
 Hungary. A 'Hunky' is not necessarily a Hungarian. He may 
 belong to any of the Slavic races. 'Ginny' seems to include all the 
 ' Hunkies ' with the Italians thrown in." The Pittsburgh Survey: The 
 Steel Workers, pp. 147-148. 
 
Racial Stratification 165 
 
 would have been, had the rate of expansion during that 
 decade been as slow as in 1880-1890. Of the total number 
 employed by Concern No. I, 8728 were Americans or older 
 immigrants; the others belonged to the new immigrant 
 races. Had the concern progressed at the 1880-1890 rate, 
 the force would have been increased by one fourth, approxi- 
 mately to 11,000. Only one half of this number, i. e., 
 5500, could have been given skilled employment, while the 
 other 2304 of the 7804 English-speaking workmen who 
 were so employed in 1907 would have had to content 
 themselves with unskilled work. In other words, a slower 
 expansion of the industry recommended by the Immigration 
 Commission 1 would have deprived more than thirty per 
 cent of the "English-speaking" workmen of opportunities 
 for advancement. Their standard of living would neces- 
 sarily have remained that of unskilled laborers. It is only 
 because the new immigration has furnished the class of 
 unskilled laborers that the native workmen and older 
 immigrants have been raised to the plane of an aristocracy 
 of labor. This evolution must not be lost sight of in the 
 discussion of "racial displacement." 
 
 That the statistics of iron and steel workers show an 
 increase of 49,000 native-born of native parentage from 
 1890 to 1900, does not mean that the same individuals were 
 employed in 1900 as ten years before. Some surely have 
 advanced on the scale of occupations and others succeeded 
 them in the mills, still the figures do not disclose the change 
 of individuals. But when English-speaking workers of 
 foreign birth are classified separately, the shifting of a 
 number of Englishmen, Welshmen, and Irishmen to other, 
 more remunerative pursuits, will manifest itself in a corre- 
 sponding reduction of their numbers employed in the iron 
 and steel industry, unless there have been new immigrants 
 of the same nationalities to take their places. This may be 
 observed in many industries. It has been shown that 
 actual displacement of native- by foreign-born wage-earners 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 45. 
 
166 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 is exceptional and negligible. But there has been a decrea & 
 of the number of English, Welsh, and Irish workers in certain 
 occupations, simultaneously with an increase of the number 
 of recent immigrants and native American workers in the 
 same occupations. Upon a superficial glance this coinci- 
 dence might be interpreted as the forcing out of Amer 
 icanized workers by immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe with a lower standard of living. Such 
 an interpretation would not harmonize with the fact 
 that new native workers of native parentage, presum- 
 ably with as high a standard of living as the Irish, have 
 entered the industry in large numbers. A comparative 
 study of the distribution of the foreign-born workers by 
 country of birth and occupation will bring out the real 
 tendencies of the industrial readjustment produced by 
 immigration. 
 
 We find in the first place, that the total number of 
 English, Welsh, Irish, and German male breadwinners 
 in the United States decreased from 1890 to 1900 as 
 follows: 
 
 TABLE 35. 
 
 NUMBER OF ENGLISH, WELSH, IRISH, AND GERMAN MALE BREADWINNERS 
 
 (THOUSANDS), 1890 and 1900. x 
 
 Nationality 
 
 Number 
 
 Decrease 1890-1900 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 English and Welsh. . . 
 Irish 
 
 487 
 80 5 
 1338 
 
 439 
 7M 
 1276 
 
 48 
 
 91 
 
 62 
 
 9-9 
 II-3 
 4.6 
 
 
 
 It must be borne in mind that the number of foreign-born 
 can increase only by immigration, since their children born 
 in this country are classified as native. Had there been no 
 immigration, the four nationalities named should have lost 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XI. 
 
Racial Stratification 167 
 
 by death from 1890 to 1900 about 20 per cent of their 
 numbers. 1 The actual per cent of decrease indicates 
 that the net immigration of the English and Welsh, 
 Irish, and Germans must have been equal respectively 
 to about 10 per cent, 9 per cent, and 15 per cent of 
 their numbers in 1890. In other words, there was no 
 " displacement" of those nationalities by the races of 
 the new immigration. 
 
 In the next place, the reduction in numbers affected only 
 certain occupations, while others showed an increase. 
 Among the English and Welsh, the latter class comprised 
 the following occupations: manufacturers, with an increase 
 of 5000; agents and salesmen, with an increase of 3900; 
 and professional men, with an increase of 2500. All other 
 occupations showed a decrease; the greatest numerical 
 decrease was found among the farmers, viz. 14,500 men, 
 or 20 per cent, which was somewhat in excess of the 
 death roll for the ten-year period. 2 Apparently, no 
 new farmers came from England and Wales to fill the 
 places of their countrymen who were carried off by death. 
 This fact, obviously, had nothing to do with the "new 
 immigration," since the "undesirable aliens from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe" kept away from the farming 
 sections and left the field open for English and Welsh 
 immigrants. 
 
 The tendency characterizing the readjustment which 
 took place in the occupational field is brought out in the 
 following comparative statement of selected occupations 
 which exhibited a marked divergence, one way or the other, 
 between the percentage of decrease of the number employed 
 and the occupational death-rate : 
 
 1 The annual death-rate among the foreign-born, according to the 
 census of 1900, varied from 19 to 20.6 per 1000. XII. Census, Vital 
 Statistics, Part I., p. xc. 
 
 a The annual death-rate for farmers and farm laborers according to 
 the XII. Census was 17.6 per 1000. XII. Census, Vital Statistics, Part 
 I., p. 209. 
 
168 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 36. 
 
 SHIFTING OF ENGLISH AND WELSH MALE BREADWINNERS IN SELECTED 
 OCCUPATIONS, 1 890-1900. 
 
 Selected occupations. 
 
 Per cent ratio to total engaged in each 
 occupation. 
 
 Aggregate 
 decrease 
 
 Loss by 
 death 
 
 Net accretion (+) 
 ordefection( ) 
 
 Bookkeepers, accountants, and 
 
 -0.6 
 
 -8.3 
 
 -2.8 
 
 -17.6 
 
 20.8 
 
 -39.5 
 
 -13.6 
 16.4 
 
 io.5 a 
 -8.8 
 -9.6 
 -H.8 
 
 + 13.0 
 
 +8.1 
 
 +77 
 -8.8 
 
 II.2 
 -277 
 
 Retail merchants 
 
 Machinists and blacksmiths 
 
 Textile mill operatives 
 
 Miners and quarrymen 
 
 Tailors 
 
 
 The preceding table indicates that while the English 
 and Welsh were leaving the mines, the textile mills, 
 and the tailor shops, their numbers were increasing in 
 some of the better paid skilled trades and in mercantile 
 pursuits. 
 
 The tendency among the Irish was substantially the same 
 as among the English and Welsh. There were 5000 more 
 manufacturers in 1900 than in 1890; 4700 more agents and 
 salesmen, and 500 more professional men. All other speci- 
 fied occupations showed a decrease. The greatest decrease, 
 both numerical and relative, appeared among farmers, viz., 
 26,000, or 28 per cent, which was much in excess of the 
 loss by death. It is evident not only that the soil had no 
 attraction for the recent Irish immigrants, but that it could 
 not hold the older Irish farmers who must have given up 
 farming for other pursuits. The direction in which the 
 Irish shifted within non-agricultural pursuits is indicated 
 in Table 37 next below: 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XI. 
 
 'The death-rate for 1900 among machinists was 10.5 and among 
 blacksmiths 18.3 per 1000. (Vital Statistics, loc. tit.) In order to 
 make the estimates in this table more conservative, the lower rate has 
 been selected. 
 
Racial Stratification 
 
 169 
 
 TABLE 37. 
 
 SHIFTING OF IRISH MALE BREADWINNERS IN SELBCTBD~OCCUPATIONS, 
 1890-1900.* 
 
 Selected occupations 
 
 Per cent ratio to total engaged in each 
 occupation 
 
 Aggregate 
 decrease 
 
 Loss by 
 death 
 
 Net accretion ( -f ) 
 or defection( ) 
 
 Bookkeepers, accountants, and 
 clerks 
 
 0.0 
 -2.3 
 -10.3 
 -I4-5 
 
 18.0 
 -25.5 
 -34-5 
 
 -13.6 
 -lo.s 1 
 17.0' 
 10.8 
 -9.6 
 -8.8 
 -II.8 
 
 + I3-6 
 
 +8.2 
 
 4-6.7 
 
 = 3 4 
 
 -157 
 -22.7 
 
 Machinists and blacksmiths . . 
 
 Building trades 
 
 Steam railroad employees 
 
 Miners and quanymen 
 
 Textile mill operatives 
 
 Tailors 
 
 
 Simultaneously with the movement of the Irish from the 
 mines, the textile mills, the tailor shops and, presumably, 
 from the lower grades of the railroad service, their number 
 increased in the skilled trades and in clerical pursuits. 
 
 The occupational changes among the Germans display 
 the same tendencies as have been traced among the English- 
 speaking races, with some variation of detail. The census 
 returns for 1900 record an increase since 1890 in the follow- 
 ing occupations : manufacturers, 7000 ; agents and salesmen, 
 1 1 ,000; professional men, 2000 ; machinists and blacksmiths, 
 3000. City laborers, farm laborers, and all other specified 
 occupations show a numerical decrease. In some of the 
 latter, however, the loss by death was partly offset by 
 accretions from the same nationality, while in others actual 
 defections added to the natural decrease by death. The 
 comparative statistics for both classes of occupations are 
 presented in the following table: 
 
 1 See footnotes to Table 36. 
 
 2 The death-rate for masons in 1900 was 19.9 per 1000; for carpenters 
 and joiners 17.2; for plasterers and whitewashes 17.0. (Vital Statis- 
 tics, loc. cit.) 
 
170 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 38. 
 
 SHIFTING OF GERMAN MALE BREADWINNERS IN SELECTED OCCUPATIONS 
 1 890-1 900. x 
 
 Selected occupations 
 
 Per cent ratio to total engaged in each 
 occupation 
 
 Aggregate 
 decrease 
 
 Loss by 
 death 
 
 Net accretion(+) 
 or defection ( - ) 
 
 Farmers 
 
 -6.7 
 
 ~4-5 
 -12.5 
 i.o 
 
 22.O 
 -22.6 
 
 -17.6 
 16.4 
 -17.0 
 -9.6 
 n.o 
 - 8.8 
 
 + 10.9 
 + II.9 
 
 +4-5 
 +8.6 
 
 IO.2 
 -13.8 
 
 
 Building trades 
 
 Miners and quarrymen 
 
 Tailors 
 
 Textile mill operatives 
 
 
 Unlike the English, Welsh, and Irish, the Germans, during 
 the last decade of the nineteenth century, show accretions 
 among the farmers, on the one hand, and among the miners 
 and quarrymen, on the other. Defections from textile mills 
 and tailor shops are paralleled by increases among retail 
 merchants and in the building trades. 
 
 The ultimate effect of immigration from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe upon the readjustment of the various races 
 of foreign-born breadwinners on the scale of occupations 
 appears from the table on page 171. 
 
 The earlier immigrants have worked their way upward, 
 leaving the coarse grades of labor to later immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. It will be observed that 
 the natives of Austria-Hungary furnish a strikingly high 
 proportion of mine, mill, and factory workers compared with 
 the Germans and Irish. The Poles and Italians furnish a 
 proportion of common laborers higher than the Irish and 
 much higher than the Germans and the British. On the 
 other hand, one fifth of the Germans and Swedes are farmers, 
 whereas the percentage of farmers among the natives of 
 Poland and Austria is very small, and among the Hun- 
 garians and Italians it is negligible. The races of the "old 
 
 1 See footnotes to Table 36. 
 
Racial Stratification 
 
 171 
 
 immigration " likewise show higher percentages of skilled 
 mechanics and of persons engaged in business and the 
 professions. 
 
 TABLE 39. 
 
 PRINCIPAL NATIONALITIES OF MALE BREADWINNERS CLASSIFIED BY 
 OCCUPATION GROUPS (PER CENT ), 1900. l 
 
 Nationality 
 
 Farmers, 
 planters, and 
 overseers 
 
 Business, pro- 
 fessional and 
 clerical pur- 
 suits* 
 
 Skilled 
 trades* 
 
 Mine, mill, 
 and factory 
 workers* 
 
 Laborers 
 (not on farms) 
 
 a 
 
 1 
 
 o 
 
 3 
 
 1 
 
 Scotch. . 
 
 12 7 
 
 18 7 
 
 16 5 
 
 
 
 
 
 English and 
 Welsh... 
 Irish . . . 
 
 I3.I 
 
 Q d. 
 
 M.O./ 
 177 
 
 12 I 
 
 i*Vd 
 
 13-2 
 
 Q 1 
 
 J 3-4 
 18.0 
 
 Q 7 
 
 7 
 6. 4 
 
 33- 
 31-6 
 
 7 Q ~ 
 
 IOO 
 
 Germans 
 
 2O 7 
 
 re -i 
 
 y-o 
 iii 
 
 8.7 
 
 ft Q 
 
 22.3 
 
 TO 2 
 
 30.2 
 
 .je a 
 
 
 Swedes 
 
 2O.Q 
 
 7.7 
 
 I -I C 
 
 u.y 
 IO Q 
 
 12 8 
 
 35- 
 *d 2 
 
 IOO 
 
 Poles . 
 
 c 7 
 
 8 7 
 
 5T 
 
 21 2 
 
 2Q I 
 
 28 2 
 
 IOO 
 
 Italians . . 
 
 1.6 
 
 10 2 
 
 * 
 
 4<7 
 
 ,}.<: 
 I/I ^ 
 
 ^y.i 
 
 3-7 2 
 
 <je a 
 
 IOO 
 
 Austrians .... 
 Hungarians. . 
 
 ?:1 
 
 10.8 
 
 8.4 
 
 z 
 
 4.6 
 
 3-0 
 
 1 '+-0 
 31-7 
 40.7 
 
 &s 
 
 22.3 
 
 OO' 
 
 28.9 
 
 24.0 
 
 IOO 
 IOO 
 
 To throw the social gradation among the various nation- 
 alities more into relief, all specified occupations of the 
 preceding table are combined in Table 40 under two heads: 
 (i) higher grade, comprising skilled mechanics, business and 
 professional men and farmers, and (2) lower grade, compris- 
 ing mine, mill, and factory workers and unskilled laborers 
 in general. Nearly one half of all the British, German, and 
 Swedish immigrants are farmers, skilled mechanics, pro- 
 fessional and business men ; less than one fourth are em- 
 ployed in the coarser grades of labor. Among the races 
 of the old immigration the proportion is reversed. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table A, pp. 821-829. 
 
 'Include: Saloonkeepers and bartenders; agents; bookkeepers and 
 accountants; clerks and copyists; merchants and dealers (not wholesale); 
 salesmen; manufacturers and officials, etc.; and professional service. 
 
 3 Include: Building trades; blacksmiths; machinists; printers, litho- 
 -.Jraphers, and pressmen, and tobacco and cigar factory operatives. 
 
 * Include: Iron and steel workers; miners and quarrymen; saw- and 
 planing-mill employees; tailors; and textile mill operatives.. 
 
172 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 40. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF FOREIGN-BORN MALE BREAD-WINNERS 
 ACCORDING TO NATIONALITY AND GRADE OF OCCUPATION, IQOO 
 
 Nationality (as determined by country of birth) 
 
 Higher-grade 
 
 Lower-grade 
 
 Scotch 
 
 47 O 
 
 TQ T 
 
 German 
 
 A"J I 
 
 17 I 
 
 English and Welsh 
 
 A A O 
 
 24. 4. 
 
 Swedes 
 
 42 I 
 
 2\ 7 
 
 Irish 
 
 IQ 8 
 
 71 T 
 
 Austrian 
 
 O w - 
 
 20. 6 
 
 CQ ^ 
 
 Polish 
 
 IQ. c 
 
 C2 -I 
 
 Italian 
 
 16.5 
 
 47 7 
 
 Hungarian 
 
 I^.O 
 
 t/ / 
 62.1 
 
 
 
 
 A comparison of the Scotch with other English-speaking 
 immigrants throws a new light upon the subject of ''racial 
 displacement." Judged by occupational standards, the 
 Scotch stand higher than other immigrants from the British 
 Isles. And yet, while the English, Welsh, and Irish in the 
 United States decreased in number from 1890 to 1900, the 
 Scotch showed an increase of 10 per cent, which was 
 equivalent to a net immigration of about 30 per cent. In- 
 creased numbers in the principal occupations are the rule 
 among the Scotch during that decade, decreases the excep- 
 tion. Even common laborers show an increase. 1 But 
 
 Sec Appendix, Table XI. 
 
 In the census returns for 1890 the distinction between agricultural 
 laborers and other laborers in agricultural districts was not strictly 
 drawn. For this reason comparisons for each class taken separately 
 are not reliable when the differences are close. The combined number 
 of city laborers and farm laborers among the Scotch was 14,300 in 1890 
 and 14,500 in 1900. The only two occupations which show a numerical 
 decrease in excess of the probable loss by death are miners and textile 
 mill operatives. The miners showed an aggregate decrease of 2100 
 men, which was equivalent to 17.8 per cent, as against a death-rate of 
 9.6 per cent; among the textile mill operatives the corresponding per- 
 centages were respectively 23.4 per cent and 8.8 per cent. The number 
 of tailors decreased from noo to 1000, which approximately corre- 
 sponds to the death-rate among tailors. 
 
Racial Stratification 173 
 
 these decreases were amply compensated by increases in 
 other occupations. These facts command attention. The 
 Scotchman's "progress toward assimilation" is not ques- 
 tioned. It is not claimed that his standard of living is 
 lower than the Irish, or the English; nor has "ready ac- 
 ceptance of a low wage," or "willingness to accept 
 indefinitely without protest certain conditions of em- 
 ployment," been discovered among his "general char- 
 acteristics." 1 The increase of the Scotch in this country, 
 contemporaneous with a decrease of the English and Irish, 
 warrants the supposition that the decline of emigration from 
 England and Ireland may be the effect of changed conditions 
 in those countries rather than in the United States. This 
 subject will be more fully treated in a subsequent chapter. 
 
 As the latest available figures for the whole country date 
 back to 1900, the question arises whether the relations 
 disclosed by them have not been materially modified by the 
 heavy immigration of the first decade of the present century. 
 A partial view of its effects, restricted to the first half of 
 that period and to one industrial State with a large foreign- 
 born population, can be gained from a comparison of the 
 results of the Massachusetts census of 1905 with those of the 
 United States census of 1900. According to the changes 
 which took place in the interval, all classes of manual labor 
 and clerical occupations fall into five groups: 
 
 I. Occupations in which the increased demand for labor 
 manifested itself in a general increase of native, as well 
 as foreign-born breadwinners. 
 
 II. Specified occupations in which the demand for labor 
 decreased, reducing both the native and the foreign-born 
 force. 
 
 III. Laborers, not specified. 
 
 IV. Occupations in which native workers were displaced 
 by immigrants. 
 
 V. Occupations in which foreign-bora workers were 
 displaced by native-born. 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t pp. 195-196. 
 
174 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Laborers have been segregated into a separate group for 
 the reason that an increase or decrease among them is 
 likely to be affected by a difference in the method of classi- 
 fication as much as by real economic changes. The com- 
 parative importance of these five groups appears from Table 
 41. The Massachusetts census draws no distinction 
 between native-born of native and of foreign parentage. 
 On the whole, native breadwinners show a greater increase 
 than foreign-born. 
 
 TABLE 41. 
 
 INCREASE (+) AND DECREASE ( ) OF THE NUMBER OF BREADWINNERS 
 IN MASSACHUSETTS CLASSIFIED BY SEX, NATIVITY, AND OCCUPATION 
 
 GROUPS (THOUSANDS), 1 900-1905. x 
 
 Nativity and Sex 
 
 
 
 Occupati 
 
 :>n groups 
 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 II 
 
 III 
 
 IV 
 
 V 
 
 Total 
 
 Both Sexes: 
 Native 
 Foreign-born 
 
 +79-9 
 
 +57-3 
 
 -I7-3 
 
 -5-8 
 
 -7.7 
 II. I 
 
 -2.8 
 
 +3-9 
 
 + 1.0 
 
 -0.4 
 
 +53-1 
 +43-9 
 
 Total 
 Male: 
 Native 
 Foreign-born 
 
 + 137-2 
 
 +48.9 
 
 +4I-5 
 
 -23.1 
 
 -12.8 
 
 -3-1 
 
 -18.8 
 
 -7.7 
 II. I 
 
 + 1.1 
 
 -2.7 
 +3-8 
 
 +0.6 
 
 +0.5 
 -0.4 
 
 +97.0 
 
 +26.2 
 +30-7 
 
 Total 
 
 Female: 
 Native 
 
 +90.4 
 -{-31.0 
 
 -15-9 
 
 4.5 
 
 -18.8 
 
 + 1.1 
 O.I 
 
 +0.1 
 
 +0.5 
 
 +56.9 
 +26.9 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 + 15-8 
 
 -2.7 
 
 
 +0.1 
 
 o.o 
 
 + 13-2 
 
 Total 
 
 +46.8 
 
 7.2 
 
 
 +O.O 
 
 +0.5 
 
 +40.1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 The increase of the native-born is greatest where the 
 increase of the foreign-born is greatest. On the contrary 
 a substantial decrease of native-born breadwinners is found 
 in the second group of occupations where the number of 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 34, pp. 154 /., and Table 41, 
 pp. 300-305. Census of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts, 1905, 
 vol. ii., Occupations, Table I., pp. 9-117. 
 
Racial Stratification 
 
 foreign-born likewise shows a large decrease. The gains of 
 the foreign-born at the expense of the native and vice-versa 
 are insignificant. The decrease of native breadwinners in 
 all occupations aggregated 27,800 persons, but it was offset 
 by a net increase of 80,900 in all other classes of manual 
 labor and clerical occupations, that is to say the loss of one 
 position was compensated by the gain of three. No account 
 is taken here of the increase of native-born breadwinners in 
 business and professional service. 
 
 As stated above, it is uncertain whether the decrease of 
 the number of laborers was due to industrial changes or to 
 the whims of statistical classification. The details for all 
 other occupations showing a decrease of the number of 
 native breadwinners are given in Table 42. 
 
 TABLE 42. 
 
 SPECIFIED OCCUPATIONS IN MASSACHUSETTS WITH A DECREASING NUM- 
 BER OF NATIVE BREADWINNERS, CLASSIFIED BY SEX AND NATIVITY, 
 1 900-1 905. * 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Decrease 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Decrease 
 (Thou- 
 sands) 
 
 GROUP II 
 
 Native 
 
 Foreign- 
 born 
 
 GROUP IV 
 
 NATIVE 
 
 Males: 
 Agricultural laborers. . . 
 Butchers 
 
 2.5 
 
 li 
 
 2.2 
 I.O 
 
 3.0 
 
 12.8 
 
 1.8 
 I.S 
 
 1.2 
 
 4-5 
 
 .3 
 .1 
 4 
 
 I.O 
 .2 
 
 I.I 
 3-1 
 
 1.5 
 .9 
 
 .2 
 
 2.6 
 
 Males. 
 Hucksters and peddlers 
 Boatmen and sailors . . . 
 Engineers and firemen . . 
 Porters and helpers 
 Tin plate ana tinware 
 
 .6 
 4 
 3 
 3 
 
 .2 
 .2 
 
 '.6 
 
 2.7 
 I 
 
 2.8 
 
 Carpenters and joiners. 
 Gold and silver workers 
 Packers and shippers . . 
 
 All others 2 
 
 Barbers and hairdressers 
 Miners and quarrymen. 
 All other" 3 
 
 Total 
 
 Females: 
 Housekeepers and 
 stewardesses 
 
 Total 
 
 Females: 
 Agricultural laborers, 
 hucksters.and peddlers 
 
 Servants and waitresses 
 
 Total 
 
 Both sexes 
 
 17-3 
 
 5.7 
 
 Both sexes 
 
 1 See footnote to Table 41. 
 
 * Includes bakers, blacksmiths, brick and "tile makers, confectioners, 
 coopers, gunsmiths, locksmiths and bell hangers, harness and saddle 
 
176 Immigration and Labor 
 
 As appears from the preceding table, the only possible 
 4 'displacement" of native- by foreign-born did not exceed 
 2800 breadwinners in five years, which was less than 3 per 
 cent of the increase of native-born in all occupations 
 exclusive of business and professional service. The total 
 number of immigrant breadwinners who gave Massachusetts 
 as their destination in 1901-1905 reached 220,000 persons 
 of both sexes. x Assuming that 2800 native hucksters and 
 peddlers, boatmen, and sailors, etc., were virtually dis- 
 placed by the immigrants, we find that the measure of 
 "displacement" was equal to one native for every seventy- 
 eight immigrants. 
 
 These results disclose no material change in the racial 
 make-up of the industrial forces during the first five years 
 of the present century; what was true in 1900 remained so as 
 late as 1905. The immigrants did not "crowd" the native 
 wage-earners, but were absorbed in those occupations where 
 native workers found employment in increasing numbers. 
 Actual "displacement" was a negligible quantity. 
 
 makers and repairers, hostlers, marble and stone cutters, masons (brick 
 and stone), meat and fruit canners, packers, etc., millers, shirt, collar 
 and cuff makers, stewards, and wheelwrights. 
 
 3 Includes brassworkers, cabinet makers, candle, soap, and tallow 
 makers, copper workers, engravers, paper hangers, rope and cordage 
 factory operatives, sail, awning, and tent makers, tobacco and cigar 
 operatives, and upholsterers. 
 
 1 Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration: 1901, 
 p. 17, Table VIII.; 1902, p. 29, Table IX.; 1903, p. 32, Table IX.; 1904, 
 p. 30, Table IX.; 1905, p. 34, Table IX. 
 
CHAPTER VIII 
 
 EMIGRATION FROM NORTHERN AND WESTERN EUROPE 
 
 A. Introductory 
 
 HTHE great influx of Italian, Slav, and Jewish immigrants 
 1 since 1890 coincides with a decrease of immigration 
 from Northern and Western Europe. This coincidence has 
 been generally accepted as proof that immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe has checked the current of 
 "more desirable*' immigration from Northern and Western 
 Europe. This assertion has been clothed in the scientific 
 garb of "the Gresham law of immigration"; bad immigra- 
 tion, it is said, tends to drive out good immigration. The 
 cum hoc, ergo propter hoc method of reasoning has scarcely 
 ever appeared so undisguised as in this newly discovered 
 "law." No attempt has been made to inquire into the 
 conditions of the countries from which the "old immigra- 
 tion" was drawn, with a view to ascertaining, if possible, 
 whether there were any causes tending to check emigration 
 from those countries. 
 
 It has been shown in Chapter TV. that in the long run 
 immigration bears an almost constant relation to the popu- 
 lation of the United States. Inasmuch, however, as the 
 latter increases faster than the population of Europe, 
 especially that of the emigration countries, the rate of 
 emigration from those countries must increase much faster 
 than their population in order to supply the industries of 
 the United States with the number of immigrants they can 
 employ. Yet the sources of emigration are not unlimited. 
 
178 Immigration and Labor 
 
 We may speak, metaphorically, of a Slav "invasion," but 
 such figures of speech merely obscure the real nature of 
 present-day phenomena. The Norman invaders of a thou- 
 sand years ago financed their expeditions by robbing the 
 peaceable population on their way. All they needed was 
 the spirit of adventure. To-day that spirit alone will not 
 carry their descendants across the ocean. The funds for 
 emigration must be raised by the emigrants themselves, or 
 by their relatives and friends. The volume of emigration 
 from a given country can, therefore, not increase beyond 
 a certain limit set by the size of its population. When 
 that point is reached, further industrial expansion in the 
 United States must draw upon the labor supply of other 
 countries. 
 
 During the ten-year period 1881-1890 the countries of 
 Northern and Western Europe furnished 72 per cent of 
 the total immigration to the United States. x This period 
 included the years of the maximum immigration from 
 Germany and the Scandinavian countries and of the great- 
 est immigration from the United Kingdom since the Irish 
 famine of the '40*8 of the past century. To maintain the 
 same ratio to the total immigration of the past decade, 
 1901-1910, the countries of Northern and Western Europe 
 should have furnished six and one third million immigrants, 
 i. e., two thirds more than in 1881-1890. In order to 
 replace the immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 that were absorbed by the industrial expansion of the past 
 decade, immigration from Northern and Western Europe 
 should have risen 117 per cent above the highest water-mark 
 reached in 1881-1890. 
 
 During the same period the population of Ireland de- 
 creased 14 per cent, and the population of the other coun- 
 tries of Northern and Western Europe increased from 
 12.5 to 25.2 per cent. 2 Unless-we allow ourselves to be 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table 6, pp. 61-63. 
 *The rates of increase for each of the principal countries were as 
 follows: 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 179 
 
 carried away by imagination, does past experience warrant 
 the assumption that the volume of immigration from those 
 countries could have so far outrun the increase of their 
 population? 
 
 The total immigration from Ireland to the United States 
 for 1891-1900 was equal to 655,000 persons. 1 An increase 
 of 117 per cent would have brought up this figure to 1,400,- 
 ooo (in round numbers), i. e., to 31 per cent of the popula- 
 tion of Ireland at the census of 1901.* Such a rate of 
 depopulation was not reached even in the years of the Irish 
 famine. 3 
 
 It is needless to repeat this calculation for Great Britain 
 and the Scandinavian countries. It could be shown by a 
 simple computation that, in order to replace the "new 
 immigration" emigration from those countries should have 
 risen to the Irish level. Their recent economic develop- 
 ment, on the contrary, as will next be shown, has had a 
 decided tendency to check emigration. 
 
 Per cent 
 
 England and Wales 1881-1901 25.2 
 
 Scotland 1881-1901 19.7 
 
 Germany 1880-1900 24.6 
 
 Denmark 1881-1900 244 
 
 Norway 1875-1900 23.1 
 
 Sweden 1880-1900 12.5 
 
 (Computed from Statesman's Year Book, 1910, pp. 13, 17; and British 
 Statistical Abstract of the Principal and Other Foreign Countries, No. 16, 
 p. 8; No. 35, pp. 8, 10.) 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table 9, pp. 89-92. 
 
 2 Statistical Abstract for the United Kingdom, Table 114, p. 361. 
 
 3 The lowest numerical and relative decrease was in 1871-1881, viz., 
 237,541 persons, equivalent to 4.4 per cent. The total emigration 
 during the same period was 618,650. The natural increase of popula- 
 tion through the excess of births over deaths was accordingly 381,109 
 persons, i. e., 7 per cent of the population at the census of 1878. 
 Allowing the same rate for the natural increase of the population of 
 Ireland in 1901-1910, we obtain 24 per cent as the rate of decrease in 
 our hypothetical case, as against 19.8 per cent for the decade 1841-1851 
 comprising the years of the great Irish famine. (The figures are taken 
 from the Statistical Abstract for the United Kingdom, No. 56, p. 361, 
 Table 114.) 
 
i8o 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 B. Germany 
 
 In the closing years of the nineteenth century Germany 
 ceased to be a country of emigration, and became a country 
 of immigration. This transformation is seen from the fol- 
 lowing table: 
 
 TABLE 43. 
 
 FOREIGN-BORN POPULATION OF GERMANY, NET EMIGRATION AND NET 
 IMMIGRATION (THOUSANDS). 1 
 
 
 Foreign-born population 
 
 
 Year 
 
 
 Increase 
 
 Net emigration ( ) 
 or 
 
 
 Number 
 
 
 net immigration ( +) 
 
 Total 
 
 Annual 
 
 
 
 
 average 
 
 
 1880 
 
 419 
 
 
 
 
 1885 
 
 433 
 
 H 
 
 3 
 
 980 
 
 1890 
 
 513 
 
 80 
 
 16 
 
 -331 
 
 1895 
 
 
 
 ... 
 
 -449 
 
 I9OO 
 
 830 
 
 317 
 
 32 
 
 + 94 
 
 1905 
 
 
 
 
 + 52 
 
 The increase of the foreign-born population of Germany 
 during the years 1 900-1 907 averaged 79,000 annually. a The 
 annual increase of the foreign-born population of the United 
 States in 1870-1880 averaged 107,000, and in 1890-1900, 
 109,000. It can be readily seen by comparison that immi- 
 gration to Germany is growing to respectable proportions. 
 Two thirds of the foreign-born male breadwinners are 
 engaged in industrial pursuits. This fact alone would 
 furnish a sufficient explanation of the decline of German 
 immigration to the United States; when there is a call for 
 large masses of immigrant labor, native wage-earners will 
 find a good market at home. 3 
 
 It is worthy of note, on the other hand, that Germany 
 
 1 Die Statisiik in Deutschland nach ihrem heutigen Stand, I Band 
 (1911), Dr. Herrmann Losch, " Wanderungsstatistik," p. 485. Dr. 
 Friedrich Zahn, " Deutschlands wirtschaftliche Entwickelung," Annalen 
 des Deutschen Reichs, 1910, p. 405. 
 
 Ibid. See Appendix, Table XII. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 181 
 
 draws her immigrant supply from the same sources as the 
 United States. During the twenty years from 1880 to 
 1900, three fourths of all immigrants to Germany came from 
 Austria-Hungary, Russia, and Italy. 1 Moreover, the Polish 
 or Italian immigrant to the United States comes from a 
 higher social layer than his countryman who goes to Ger- 
 many, the cost of passage from any of these countries to 
 Germany being purely nominal in comparison with the cost 
 of a transatlantic trip. It is evident that the German 
 wage-earner cannot avoid coming in contact with the immi- 
 grant from Southern and Eastern Europe by staying away 
 from the United States. 
 
 In addition to her permanent foreign-born population 
 Germany has a large floating immigrant labor supply, the 
 so-called "birds of passage," mostly Poles and other 
 Slavs from Russia and Galicia. The latest official data 
 relating to migration from Galicia to Germany place the 
 total number at 26,283 for the year 1899. The movement 
 has considerably grown since that time. Austrian statis- 
 ticians variously estimate the number for the year 1905 at 
 from 60,000 to 100,000. 3 
 
 The migration of working men and women from Russian 
 Poland to Germany for temporary employment has grown 
 in the following proportion: 
 
 TABLE 44* 
 
 MIGRATION OF WORKERS FROM RUSSIAN POLAND TO GERMANY FOR 
 TEMPORARY EMPLOYMENT, 1890-1904.* 
 
 Year Thousands 
 
 1890 17 
 
 1900 119 
 
 1901 140 
 
 1902 136 
 
 1903 142 
 
 1904 138 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XIII. 
 
 * Munchener Volkswirtschaftliche Studicn, J. von Trzcinski, "Russisch- 
 Polnische und galizische Wanderarbeiter im Grossherzogtum Posen," 
 p. 44. 
 
 a Reports of the Warsaw Statistical Committee. Bulletin XXII. t p. 2, 
 
1 82 Immigration and Labor 
 
 About 95 per cent of the temporary immigrants from 
 Russian Poland find employment as agricultural laborers. 1 
 But the demand for them is the direct result of the move- 
 ment of Polish peasants from the rural districts of Prussian 
 Poland to the great industrial cities of Germany and 
 particularly to the coal mining districts. 
 
 In 1898 there were 57,000 foreign-speaking mine workers 
 in Western Germany out of a total of 198,000, i. e., 28.7 
 per cent, nearly all of whom were Poles from Prussian 
 Poland. 2 According to the latest statistics for the Ruhr 
 district, which produces one half of Germany's coal output, 
 the number of Polish miners has grown to 100,000 out of a 
 total of 350,000. 3 Evidently, there must have been some 
 other cause than reluctance to compete with Polish immi- 
 grants that has " operated to prevent the further coming" 
 of German miners to the bituminous regions of Pennsyl- 
 vania, 4 since they have no alternative but to work with 
 Polish immigrants on either side of the Atlantic. 
 
 The transformation of Germany from an emigrant- 
 furnishing nation to a country of immigration is the direct 
 result of her recent industrial expansion. Its extent can be 
 gauged by the comparative growth of production of coal 
 and pig iron in Germany and the two other leading indus- 
 trial countries, the United States and Great Britain, as 
 represented graphically in Diagrams XII s and XIII. 6 In 
 coal mining Germany has, in recent years, outrun Great 
 
 Warsaw, 1906. (In Russian.) General Analysis .of the Statistics of 
 Migration of Workers for Temporary Employment, etc. By K. G. 
 Vobly. * Ibid., p. 21. 
 
 3 J. Karski, Die Polnischen Wanderarbeiter, "Die Neue Zeit," 1900- 
 1901, pp. 722, 723. 
 
 3V. Maisky: "The Tragedy of the German Coal Miners," (in 
 Russian) Russkoye Bogatstvo, April, 1912, pp. 35, 47. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 427. 
 
 s Based upon the Report of the United States Geological Survey, 
 Production of Coal in 1909, p. 60. 
 
 6 Figures are taken from The Mineral Industry, 1893, P- 35 1; 1896, 
 p. 334; 1900, p. 395; 1910, p. 381. 
 
DIAGRAM xn. 
 
 Per cent of 
 
 increase of 
 
 (lie production 
 
 of coal in 
 
 the 
 
 United States, 
 Germany, 
 
 and 
 
 Great Britain, 
 1890-1909. 
 
 5s* ^ 
 
 DIAGRAM XIII. 
 
 Production of pig iron in Germany, the United States, and the 
 United Kingdom, 1880-1910. 
 
 183 
 
184 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Britain. The production of pig iron in Germany increased, 
 within the past twenty years, much faster than in Great 
 Britain; the German rate of growth was not far behind the 
 American. 
 
 Another index of German industrial progress is furnished 
 by the development of her railway system and freight 
 traffic since 1890. Comparative statistics for Germany 
 and the United States are given in Table 45. 
 
 TABLE 45. 
 
 COMPARATIVE GROWTH OF RAILROAD MILEAGE AND FREIGHT TRAFFIC 
 IN GERMANY AND THE UNITED STATES, 1 890-1900. x 
 
 Country 
 
 Per cent IB 
 
 crease 
 
 
 Mileage in operation 
 
 Ton -miles of freight 
 
 
 41.3 
 
 n 1 ?.? 
 
 United States 
 
 46.7 
 
 18-1.4 
 
 
 
 
 The full import of the preceding figures can only be 
 realized if one bears in mind the much smaller area and the 
 greater density of population of Germany, compared with 
 the United States, both factors reducing the distance from 
 mine to mill and from mill to market. 
 
 The use of mechanical power in the industrial establish- 
 ments of Germany more than doubled within the short 
 space of twelve years, viz., from 3,400,000 in 1895 to 
 8,800,000 in 1907." 
 
 1 Computed from the following sources: Dr. Friedrich Zahn, "Deutsch- 
 lands wirtschaftliche Entwickelung," Annalen des Deutschen Reichs, 
 1911, No. 3-4, p. 189; Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, 
 
 P- 715. 
 
 a Zahn, he. cit. t p. 175. 
 
, From Northern and Western Europe 185 
 
 The effect of the industrial progress of Germany upon 
 the labor market is shown in the comparative increase 
 of the number of breadwinners engaged in trade and 
 manufactures and of the population at large, as shown 
 in Table 46 next following: 
 
 TABLE 46. 
 
 PER CENT INCREASE OF THE POPULATION OF GERMANY AND OF THE 
 
 NUMBER OF BREADWINNERS IN TRADE AND MANUFACTURES, 
 
 1882-1907.' 
 
 Period 
 
 Population 
 
 Breadwinners 
 
 1882-1895 
 
 H-5 
 
 39-9 
 
 1895-1907 
 
 19.2 
 
 397 
 
 The increased demand for labor in the industrial estab- 
 lishments of Germany resulted in a substantial increase 
 of the rate of wages. 
 
 " The rate of wages has risen during the recent past . . . 
 more than the price of the necessities of life, showing that 
 the German workingman has shared in the prosperity of 
 the country. " a It is admitted by the German trade-unions 
 that the condition of labor has materially improved. 8 
 
 1 Zahn, loc. cit., p. 164. 
 
 3 Earl Dean Howard: The Cause and Extent of the Recent Industrial 
 Progress of Germany, p. 118. 
 
 3 Zahn, loc. cit., p. 227. If an opinion coming from official sources 
 is preferred, the following quotation from a recent speech by Mr. von 
 Berlepsch, former Prussian Minister of Commerce, will be of interest: 
 "Slowly and by little steps rises the well-being of the general body of the 
 people; and no small number of those classes of the population which 
 thirty years ago obtained a bare subsistence have now made their way 
 into a middle class and enjoy a fairly adequate income. " Howard, 
 loc. cit., p, 181. 
 
1 86 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The average annual earnings upon which membership dues 
 to the trade-union insurance fund were figured increased 
 from 638 marks in 1890 to 953 marks in 1909, i. e., 50 per 
 cent. The upward tendency of wages is not confined to the 
 skilled trades, but has affected all classes of labor. Un- 
 biased evidence of this fact is furnished by the statistics 
 compiled by local authorities under the provisions of the 
 sick-insurance law, and showing the prevailing rates of 
 wages of day laborers in the large cities. x 
 
 The rate of increase of the average annual earnings of 
 coal miners appears from the following table: 
 
 TABLE 47. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS IN PRUSSIAN COAL MINES, 
 
 District 
 
 Number of 
 wage-earners 
 (thousands) 
 1910 
 
 Annual earnings, marks 
 
 1890 
 
 1910 
 
 Per cent 
 of increase 
 
 Upper Silesia 
 
 116 
 
 28 
 
 335 
 
 22 
 
 40 
 
 6 7 I 
 
 735 
 1,067 
 878 
 730 
 
 964 
 
 974 
 1,382 
 
 1,375 
 1,089 
 
 43-6 
 
 32-5 
 24.8 
 56.6 
 49.1 
 
 Lower Silesia 
 
 Dortmund 
 
 Aix-la-Chapelle 
 
 Halle 
 
 
 At the same time there has been a marked reduction in the 
 number of hours of work per day. 3 Furthermore "there is 
 also less changing of employment and less non-employment 
 in Germany," than in the United States, since, "in most 
 cases the law requires at least a two weeks' notice before the 
 employee can be discharged." 4 
 
 All these improvements are in no small degree due to the 
 progress of organization among German wage-earners, 
 which became possible only after the repeal of the anti- 
 Socialist law on October i, 1890.^ Under the operation of 
 
 1 Howard, loc. cit., pp. 114-115. Statistical tables on the subject of 
 wages are given on pp. 112-113. _ a Zahn, loc. cit., p. 228. 
 
 3 Howard, loc. eit., p. 117. v. / ^f * Ibid., pp. 126-127. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 187 
 
 that law, only local trade-unions, without national affilia- 
 tions, had been tolerated, and those, only so long as they 
 confined themselves to mutual benefit and educational 
 objects; by executive order of April n, 1886, strikes of any 
 character were declared to be "revolutionary manifesta- 
 tions." The first national labor convention was held in 
 1892. It was not until January i, 1900, however, that all 
 laws restricting the right of federating independent local 
 unions were unequivocally repealed. 1 Since that time 
 the membership of labor organizations has progressed by 
 leaps and bounds, leaving behind the older British and 
 American trade-unions, as appears from the following table : 
 
 TABLE 48. 
 
 MEMBERSHIP OF TRADE-UNIONS IN GERMANY, 1 890-1900.* 
 
 Year (Thousands) 
 
 1890 . 301 
 
 National unions: 
 
 1900 932 
 
 1901 935 
 
 1902 1017 
 
 1903 1191 
 
 1904 W 
 
 1905 1727 
 
 1906 2129 
 
 1907 2330 
 
 1908 2203 
 
 1909 2212 
 
 1910 2435 
 
 Total, including unaffiliated local 
 unions, 1910: 
 
 Germany 2688 
 
 United States and Canada (estimated) 262 5 
 Great Britain and Ireland 2427 
 
 The ratio of organized workers to the total number of 
 wage-earners enumerated in 1907 was estimated at 28 per 
 cent. 3 
 
 1 Handwdrterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, vol. iv., pp. 1147-1149. 
 
 a Statistische Beilage des Correspondenz-Blatt der General-Commission 
 der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands , 1911, No. 6, pp. 161-163; New York 
 Labor Bulletin, No. 48 (September, 1911), P- 4*8. The membership 
 for the United States and Canada seems overestimated. 
 
 a Handwdrterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, vol. iv., p. 1175. 
 
188 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 A noteworthy development of the German labor move- 
 ment is the progress of organization among female wage- 
 earners, who are, as a rule, unorganized in this country. 
 The efforts of German unions among the women were 
 stimulated, above all altruistic considerations, by recogni- 
 tion of the depressing effect of the competition of unorgan- 
 ized female labor upon the wages of men. The extent to 
 which the women have responded to the efforts of the 
 unions can be measured by the following figures: 
 
 TABLE 49. ] 
 
 PROGRESS OF ORGANIZATION AMONG FEMALE WAGE- EARNERS, IN 
 GERMANY, 1895-1910.* 
 
 Year 
 
 Number of organized women 
 (thousands) 
 
 Per cent of total union 
 membership 
 
 1895 
 
 7 
 
 2.7 
 
 1000 
 
 23 
 
 3-3 
 
 1905 
 
 74 
 
 5-7 
 
 1906 
 
 119 
 
 7-1 
 
 1007 
 
 137 
 
 7.3 
 
 1908 
 
 138 
 
 7.6 
 
 1009 
 
 134 
 
 7-3 
 
 1910 
 
 162 
 
 8.0 
 
 The assistance rendered by German unions to their 
 members can be measured by the expenditures of the Social- 
 democratic Gewerkschaften, i. e., the national unions affili- 
 ated with the largest and most influential of the German 
 federations of labor. The figures are given in Table 50. 
 
 The progress of the labor movement in Germany has 
 directly and indirectly stimulated labor legislation, which 
 has resulted in a material improvement of the condition 
 of labor: 
 
 As a rule [says Dr. Howard], the factories are kept in a much better 
 condition, and have more arrangements for the comfort of the men, 
 
 1 Statistische Beilage des Correspondenz-Blatt der General-Commission 
 der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands, 1911, No. 6, pp. 163, 168.' 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 189 
 
 than in the United States. This is the general opinion of writers who 
 compare the conditions prevailing in the two countries, and it seems 
 to be confirmed by direct observation. The factories usually have 
 good light and air, are clean and orderly. The sanitary arrangements 
 and the facilities for washing and changing clothes are splendid. Most 
 of the factories are provided with lockers for the men, so that they 
 need not leave the place in their working clothes. 1 
 
 i TABLE 50. 
 
 COMPARATIVE SUMMARY OF THE PRINCIPAL EXPENSES OF THE NATIONAL 
 
 ORGANIZATIONS AFFILIATED WITH THE " GENERAL COMMISSION 
 
 OF THE TRADE-UNIONS OF GERMANY," 1895-1910. a 
 
 Object 
 
 Millions of marks 
 
 1895 
 
 I90O 
 
 1910 
 
 Strikes ... 
 
 0-3 
 O.2 
 
 0-5 
 
 2.7 
 
 0.5 
 
 I.O 
 
 20.4 
 6.1 
 
 11.2 
 
 
 Sick and death benefits and sundry 
 benevolent expenses 
 
 
 Germany was the first nation to introduce a system of 
 workingmen's insurance under the control of the govern- 
 ment. "The introduction of insurance laws protecting the 
 workingman against sickness and accidents, and promising 
 him a pension in his old age, has had a tendency to decrease 
 the chances of misfortune in life. " 3 
 
 In 1909 there were insured under the provisions of that 
 law over 13,000,000 persons against sickness, over 15,000,000 
 against old age and invalidity, and nearly 24,000,000 
 persons against accident, in a total population of 64,000,000 
 of whom there were less than 19,000,000 wage-earners. 4 
 
 The expansion of industry and the resulting improvement 
 of the condition of industrial wage-earners have drawn to 
 the cities and mining sections the whole natural increase 
 of the rural population. 5 
 
 1 Howard, loc. cit., pp. 127-128. 
 
 3 Ibid., p. 189. 3 Ibid., pp. 124, 131. 
 
 <Zahn, loc. cit., Annalen des Deutschen Reichs, 1911, p. 232. 
 
 s At the foundation of the German Empire in 1871, its rural popula- 
 
190 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 At the same time, German agriculture, stimulated by 
 the increase of the country's population and fostered by 
 a protective tariff, also showed substantial progress, as 
 can be seen from Table 51 below. As a result, there is a 
 scarcity of agricultural laborers during the busy season, 
 which is only partially relieved by the immigration of 
 Polish and Russian temporary laborers. Although organi- 
 zation among agricultural laborers is seriously restricted 
 by law, yet, as an effect of economic causes alone, the wages 
 of agricultural laborers have continually advanced. x 
 
 TABLE 51. 
 
 AGRICULTURAL PROGRESS IN GERMANY, 1895-1909. a 
 
 Crop 
 
 Total yield 
 Millions of tons 
 
 Yield per hectar 
 tons 
 
 1895 
 
 1909 
 
 I89S 
 
 1909 
 
 Rye 
 
 7-7 
 
 I: 
 3 L 8 
 
 11.4 
 
 3-8 
 
 2' 5 
 46.7 
 
 9.1 
 
 1-3 
 1.6 
 
 i-7 
 12.4 
 1.6 
 
 1.9 
 
 2.1 
 2.1 
 I4.I 
 2.1 
 
 Wheat. . . 
 
 Spring barley 
 
 Potatoes 
 
 Oats 
 
 
 The combined effect of all these causes was reflected in 
 the rate of emigration from rural districts. Towards the 
 middle of the past century the growth of land values had 
 made the primitive methods of farming unprofitable, and 
 necessitated the introduction of more intensive systems of 
 cultivation. In Prussian Poland the change was somewhat 
 retarded by its general economic backwardness, but in the 
 '70*8 and in the early '8o's it drove large numbers of Polish 
 peasants to the United States. These Poles constituted a 
 large element of the German immigration to the United 
 States and were counted in our immigration statistics as 
 
 tion constituted 64 per cent in a total of 41,000,000; at the census of 
 1900 the total population numbered 56,000,000, but the proportion of 
 rural population had declined to 46 per cent. Howard, loc. cit., p. 31. 
 
 1 Howard, loc. cit., p. 68. 
 
 * Zahn, loc. cit., Annalen des Deutschen Reichs, 1910, p. 578. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 191 
 
 ''Germans." 1 But the rapid development of German 
 industry within the last twenty-five years opened for these 
 peasants new opportunities at home. This fact, coupled 
 with the disappearance of cheap lands in the United States, 
 has resulted in a falling off in the emigration of farmers and 
 farm laborers to the United States. 
 
 As a general rule, industrial progress in modern times has 
 tended to eliminate the independent artisan, the small 
 trader, and the small-scale fanner and to push them into 
 the ranks of wage-earners. In Germany, however, this pro- 
 cess has been checked by the development of co-operation. 2 
 Its recent progress can be seen from the following table: 
 
 TABLE 52. 
 
 CO-OPERATIVE ASSOCIATIONS IN GERMANY, 1903-1908.3 
 
 Year 
 
 Number of 
 Associations 
 (thousands) 
 
 Membership 
 (millions) 
 
 Per cent ratio to 
 population 
 
 1903 
 
 21 
 
 3-1 
 
 54 
 
 1904 
 
 22 
 
 34 
 
 5-8 
 
 1905 
 
 24 
 
 3-6 
 
 6.2 
 
 1906 
 
 25 
 
 3-8 
 
 6-3 
 
 1907 
 
 26 
 
 4.0 
 
 6.7 
 
 1908 
 
 27 
 
 4-3 
 
 7.2 
 
 The general improvement of the living conditions of the 
 broad masses, which characterizes the recent economic de- 
 velopment of Germany, must necessarily have affected the 
 rate of emigration during the past twenty years. On the 
 other hand, the tide of German emigration in the early 
 '8o's was swelled by political oppression. Under the ' ' minor 
 state of siege, " proclaimed by virtue of the anti-Socialist 
 law of 1878, all labor unions were "put under the ban alike 
 with the political organizations of the Social- Democracy. 
 Of the 25 existing unions 1 6 were dissolved by the govern- 
 
 1 Trzcinski, loc. cit. t pp. 3 and 128. 
 
 3 Zahn: Annalen des Deutschen Reichs, 191 1, No. 3-4, p. 226. 
 
 3 Ibid., p. 227. 
 
192 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ment, the others disbanded voluntarily." 1 The member- 
 ship of the organizations directly affected was estimated at 
 50,000. The widespread discontent created by these re- 
 pressive measures led many workingmen to seek liberty 
 in the United States. The repeal of the ' ' exceptional laws " 
 in 1890 removed the political stimulus to emigration. 
 
 The cumulative effect of all these causes upon emigration 
 from Germany can be learned from the following table. 
 
 TABLE 53. 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE IMMIGRATION FROM GERMANY (THOUSANDS), 
 
 1875-1910.' 
 
 Occupation 
 
 1875-1878 
 
 1879 -1890 
 
 1891-1898 
 
 1899-1910 
 
 Skilled mechanics 
 
 4.8 
 
 1C. I 
 
 6.3 
 
 II. 5 
 
 Farmers and farm 
 laborers . ... 
 
 5.7 
 
 12.2 
 
 A A 
 
 8.O* 
 
 Laborers 
 
 -1.4. 
 
 2O.I 
 
 8.1 
 
 7.e 
 
 
 .6 
 
 2.6 
 
 2.0 
 
 7.-1 
 
 All other miscellaneous . 
 
 3-3 
 
 4-3 
 
 2.2 
 
 3-9 
 
 Total 
 
 15.8 
 
 C4..-J 
 
 2-i.q 
 
 38.2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 In 1879-1890, contemporaneously with the operation of 
 the exceptional laws of 1878, the average annual immigra- 
 tion from Germany to the United States rose 244 per cent 
 above the average level of the preceding four-year period. 
 On the other hand, the average for the twelve-year period 
 1899-1910 dropped only one third below the level of the 
 preceding period of equal length, 1879-1890. The immi- 
 gration of skilled mechanics decreased by 3600 annually, 
 
 1 Handw orterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, vol. iv., p. 1146. 
 
 9 Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance, June, 1903, pp. 
 4408-4411. Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 100. 
 Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration: 1890-1900, 
 Table VII.; 1901-1904, Table IX.; 1905-1908, Table VIII.; 1900-1910, 
 Table X. 
 
 a Of this number 1 1 10 were farmers and the rest farm laborers. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 193 
 
 i. e. t by about one fourth. The immigration of fanners and 
 farm laborers dropped 4200 annually, *. e., more than one 
 third, from the high level reached in 1879-1890. The 
 decrease of the immigration of agricultural workers doubt- 
 less bears some relation to the decline in the demand for 
 agricultural labor and the increase of land values in the 
 United States. 
 
 In order to determine the effect, if any, of immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe upon immigration from 
 Germany, the annual average immigration of unskilled 
 laborers must be considered. The line of demarkation 
 between farm laborers and "laborers not specified" was 
 not clearly drawn in our earlier immigration statistics. 
 Moreover, many agricultural laborers come to the United 
 States to seek industrial employment. If both classes of 
 laborers are merged into one, and an allowance is made 
 for the number of farmers combined with farm laborers 
 prior to 1899,* the immigration of unskilled laborers may 
 be estimated for 1891-1898 at 11,400 persons annually. 
 In 1899-1910 this average rose to 14,400. At the same 
 time the rate of immigration from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe rose from 48 per cent of the total immigration for 
 the first period, to 72 per cent for the last. 2 It is evident 
 that the competition of the Italian and Slav unskilled la- 
 borer did not deter the German unskilled laborer from com- 
 ing to the United States. On the whole, the average annual 
 immigration from Germany during the period 1899-1910 
 increased by 14,300, i. e., 60 per cent over the average for 
 1891-1898. 
 
 1 The average number of farmers for the period 1891-1898 was es- 
 timated at 1 100 annually, the same as recorded by immigration statis- 
 tics for 1899-1910, although the combined number of farmers and farm 
 laborers during the former period was only about one half of the total 
 for the latter. In this manner every precaution was taken against 
 overrating the increase of immigration of unskilled laborers during the 
 last period. 
 
 2 Computed from Reports of the Immigration Commission , vol. I, 
 Table 6, pp. 61-64. 
 
194 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The United States has always been the chief destination 
 of the bulk of German emigrants. Complete data regarding 
 the destination of German emigrants are available only 
 since 1890. The figures will be found in Table 54 next 
 following, with the rate of immigration from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe to the United States in a parallel column. 
 The results are presented graphically in Diagram XIV. 
 
 TABLE 54. 
 
 EMIGRATION FROM GERMANY TO ALL COUNTRIES OUTSIDE TEE UNITED 
 STATES, 1890-1904. x 
 
 Year 
 
 Number of emigrants from 
 Germany to countries 
 outside of United 
 States 
 
 Immigration from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe to the 
 United States, per 
 cent of total 
 
 1890 
 
 7338 
 
 35-3 
 
 1891 
 
 7043 
 
 41.2 
 
 1892 
 1893 
 
 4533 
 9428 
 
 46.6 
 44-3 
 
 1894 
 
 5062 
 
 44.9 
 
 1895 
 
 4995 
 
 42.1 
 
 1896 
 
 4817 
 
 57-0 
 
 1897 
 
 
 56.8 
 
 1898 
 
 3658 
 
 62.4 
 
 1899 
 
 4518 
 
 68.0 
 
 1900 
 1901 
 
 2161 
 
 72.4 
 73-6 
 
 1902 
 
 2887 
 
 75-1 
 
 1903 
 
 2661 
 
 72.1 
 
 1904 
 
 1899 
 
 68.4 
 
 The preceding table and Diagram XIV clearly show the 
 absence of any connection between emigration from Ger- 
 many and immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 to the United States. Emigration from Germany to other 
 countries was highest in 1890, 1891, and 1893, when immi- 
 gration from Southern and Eastern Europe to the United 
 States varied from 35.3 to 44.3 per cent of the total immi- 
 gration to the United States. Since 1893 emigration from 
 
 1 Vierteljahrshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs, 1905. Die 
 iiberseeische Auswanderung im Jahre 1904, Part I., p. 120, Table I. 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, Table 6, p. 61. 
 
DIAGRAM XIV. 
 
 S 
 
 XT7. Emigration from Germany to all countries outside of the United States 
 
 and per cent of Southern and Eastern European immigration to the total 
 
 immigration to the United States, 1890-1904. 
 
 19$ 
 
196 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Germany to other countries than the United States steadily 
 declined, while immigration from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe to the United States advanced from 44.3 to 75.1 
 per cent of the total. 
 
 It is, evidently, not because living conditions in the 
 United States have grown worse, but because living con- 
 ditions in Germany have grown better, that emigration 
 from Germany to all countries has fallen off. 
 
 C. The Scandinavians 
 
 Scandinavian immigration to the United States reached 
 its maximum during the decade 1881-1890, when it exceeded 
 by about two thirds the total for the preceding sixty years. x 
 Yet while the total number of immigrants of both sexes and 
 all ages in 1901-1910 fell short of the maximum reached in 
 1881-1890, the number of breadwinners showed a very 
 substantial increase, as appears from the following table: 
 
 TABLE 55. 
 
 SCANDINAVIAN IMMIGRATION TO THE UNITED STATES, 
 
 
 
 Breadwinners 
 
 Period 
 
 Total 
 (thousands) 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent ratio 
 
 to total 
 
 
 
 (thousands) 
 
 Scandinavian immigration 
 
 1881-1890 
 1891-1900 
 
 656 
 
 372 
 
 356 
 2 4 I 
 
 it 
 
 
 I90I-I9IO 
 
 530 
 
 429 
 
 81 
 
 
 1 The total number admitted up to 1880 was 397,011, the total for 
 1881-1890 was 656,494. Computed from Reports of the Immigration 
 Commission, vol. I, Table 9, pp. 66-96. 
 
 a Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance, June, 1903, pp. 
 4408-441 1 ; Report of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , Tables 12-13. 
 Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration: 1899-1900, 
 Table VIII.; 1901-1904, Table IX.; I9o5"-i9o8, Table VIII. ; 1909-1910, 
 Table X. 
 
 All immigrants exclusive of dependents, described in immigration 
 statistics as "without occupation (mostly women and children)." 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 197 
 
 As shown by the figures, the number of Scandinavians 
 coming to compete in the American labor market actually 
 increased: the total for 1901-1910 exceeded by 20 per cent 
 that for 1881-1890. The population of the Scandinavian 
 countries increased at the same time approximately 22 
 per cent. T Emigration kept pace with population. 
 
 The only observable change is that, whereas the earlier 
 Scandinavian immigration was mostly of a family type, 
 among the recent Scandinavian immigrants single persons 
 vastly predominate; in 1881-1890 there were 46 dependents 
 to every 54 immigrant breadwinners, in 1901-1910 only 
 19 to 81. In this respect the Scandinavian immigrants of 
 the present day are very much like the immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. The cause of this change 
 in the matter of the family relations of the Scandinavian 
 immigrants is evidently not racial, but economic. The old 
 Scandinavian immigration came largely to settle on farms,* 
 where a family was a help, while the new Scandinavian 
 immigration, like the new immigration from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe, comes chiefly to seek industrial em- 
 ployment. A single person, without family responsibilities, 
 can more easily hazard the uncertainties of emigration 
 to a strange land; a married wage-earner will as a rule leave 
 his family behind, until he feels certain of his ability to 
 provide for them in the new country. 
 
 That Scandinavian immigration to the United States 
 was in no way affected by immigration from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe is evidenced by the change in the direction 
 
 1 Computed from Statistical Abstract of the Principal and other Foreign 
 Countries (British}, No. XVI., p. 8; No. XXXV., pp. 8, 10. 
 
 a At the census of 1900, 49.8 per cent of all Norwegians, 42.3 per 
 cent of all Danes, and 30.2 per cent of all Swedes in the United States 
 were reported as engaged in agricultural pursuits. It is probable that 
 some of those who were described by the enumerators in agricultural 
 districts as laborers were agricultural laborers. Both groups com 
 bined numbered 59.3 per cent of all Norwegians, 52.3 per cent of all 
 Danes, and 43 percent of all Swedes. Reports of the Immigration Com- 
 mission, vol. 28, Table IA, pp. 216 et seq. 
 
198 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the former; whereas prior to 1890 the greater part of 
 Scandinavian immigration was directed to the agricultural 
 States of the Central West and the Northwest, since 1890 
 the majority of the Scandinavian immigrants follow the 
 current of immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 The figures are presented in Table 56. The increase of the 
 number of foreign-born from Scandinavian countries and 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe in 1880-1910 represents 
 the net results of immigration from those countries, as 
 reduced by emigration and death. In Diagram XV a 
 graphic representation of the same figures is furnished, 
 each number being expressed in the area of the correspond- 
 ing semicircle or quadrant. The black quadrants rep- 
 resent Scandinavians, the shaded semicircles and quadrants 
 natives of Southern and Eastern Europe. The left side 
 represents the eleven Western States indicated on the map, 
 the right side, all other States and Territories. 
 
 TABLE 56. 
 
 INCREASE OF FOREIGN-BORN FROM THE SCANDINAVIAN COUNTRIES AND 
 
 FROM EASTERN AND SOUTHERN EUROPE, 1880-1910, BY 
 
 GEOGRAPHIC DIVISIONS (THOUSANDS). 1 
 
 Period 
 
 Scandinavians 
 
 Natives of Southern and 
 Eastern Europe 
 
 Eleven 
 Western 
 States 
 
 All other 
 States and 
 Territories 
 
 Eleven 
 Y/estern 
 States 
 
 All other 
 States and 
 Territories 
 
 1880-1890 
 
 251 
 
 3 ^ 
 
 242 
 9 2 
 
 99 
 
 45 
 39 
 189 
 
 474 
 
 976 
 2850 
 
 1890-1900 
 
 19001910 . 
 
 
 If it were true that the Scandinavians stayed away from 
 the United States because they were reluctant to compete 
 with immigrants from Southern ^and Eastern Europe, we 
 should expect to find that the recent Scandinavian immi- 
 grants, like their predecessors, were headed for the West 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XIV. 
 
199 
 
200 Immigration and Labor 
 
 where the field was comparatively clear, and avoided those 
 States which attracted the bulk of immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. Table 56 and Diagram XV 
 furnish clear proof to the contrary. From 1880 to 1890 the 
 net accessions to the Scandinavian population were about 
 evenly divided between the western agricultural States, 
 where immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 was insignificant, and the rest of the United States, where 
 the Scandinavians were outnumbered by the races of South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe. (See the circle on the left ; com- 
 pare the two black quadrants with each other and with 
 the shaded quadrant and semicircle on each side.) At the 
 end of the next ten years, the Western States, where the 
 accretions from Southern and Eastern Europe had declined, 
 held only one third of the net gains of the Scandinavian 
 population, while two thirds were distributed over other 
 States, where they had to face ten times as many new 
 competitors from Southern and Eastern Europe. (See 
 the circle in the middle; repeat the same comparisons, as 
 above.) Again during the past decade most of the new 
 Scandinavian population sought employment in these 
 States, where they were overwhelmed by the enormous 
 tide of immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe, 
 and only a minority settled in the West, where there were 
 comparatively few newcomers from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe. (See the circle on the right; repeat the same 
 comparisons as above.) 
 
 It is evident that the Scandinavian immigrant did not 
 seek to avoid the competition of the Italian and the Slav. 
 Nor did the average Scandinavian immigrant at any time 
 display such superior skill as would place him above the 
 competition of the immigrant from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe. Most of the Scandinavian immigrants, like the 
 Slavs and the Italians, come from rural districts. 1 The 
 
 1 According to Swedish official statistics, the ratio of emigrants from 
 rural districts to the total emigration was 76 per cent in 1891-1900 
 and 77 per cent in 1901-1908. (Computed from Gustav Sundbarg's 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 201 
 
 distribution of Scandinavian immigrants by occupation has 
 undergone no material change since 1881, as witnessed by 
 the following table: 
 
 TABLE 57. 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF SCANDINAVIAN IMMIGRANT BREADWINNERS BY MAIN 
 CLASSES OF OCCUPATIONS (THOUSANDS), 
 
 Occupations 
 
 1881-1890 
 
 1891-1900 
 
 I9OI-I9ZO 
 
 
 46 
 
 je 
 
 OI 
 
 Agricultural workers, laborers, 
 
 70S 
 
 2O2 
 
 y* 
 
 72^ 
 
 All others 
 
 c 
 
 
 T-i 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 156 
 
 24.1 
 
 A2Q 
 
 
 
 
 
 While there were twice as many skilled mechanics among 
 the Scandinavian immigrants in 1901-1910 as in 1881-1890, 
 yet the bulk of them have always been laborers or farm 
 workers without special mechanical skill. The number of 
 unskilled laborers in 1901-1910 was greater than in 1881- 
 1890, and it was these . unskilled Scandinavian laborers 
 that sought employment in competition with unskilled 
 Slav and Italian laborers. If the increase of immigration 
 from the Scandinavian countries was not fast enough to 
 satisfy the preference of certain social theorists for the races 
 of Northern Europe, the explanation of this comparatively 
 slow growth must be sought in the economic conditions of 
 those countries, not in the immigration from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe to the United States. 
 
 Ekonomisk-Statistisk Beskrifning ofver Sveriges Olika Landsdelar, p. 20, 
 Table 22.) See footnotes to Table 55. 
 
 2 From a comparison of the distribution of the Scandinavian immi- 
 grants by occupation in our immigration statistics with the Swedish 
 statistics of occupations of emigrants, it appears that the distinction 
 between agricultural workers, laborers, and servants in our official 
 statistics is not reliable. (Compare American sources cited in footnote 
 to Table 55 and " Gustav Sundbarg, op. cit., p. 20, Table 22.) 
 
202 Immigration and Labor 
 
 D. Norway 
 
 The merging of all Scandinavians into one racial group in 
 United States statistics has obscured the fact that while 
 the total immigration from Sweden and Denmark (includ- 
 ing dependents) has declined since 1881-1890, immigra- 
 tion from Norway reached its maximum during the decade 
 1901-1910, as shown in the table next below: 
 
 TABLE 58. 
 
 IMMIGRATION FROM NORWAY TO THE UNITED STATES.* 
 
 Period Number 
 
 Up to 1880 148,341 
 
 1881-1890 176,586 
 
 1891-1900 95,014 
 
 I90I-I9IO 190,505 
 
 Total 610,446 
 
 The number of Norwegian immigrants of both sexes 
 and all ages in 1901-1910 was double the total for the pre- 
 ceding ten-year period and 8 per cent above the high water- 
 mark reached in 1881-1890. All that can be said is that 
 the rate of increase of the population of Norway from 1875 
 to 1900 was 23.1 per cent, i. e., approximately 18 per cent 
 in twenty years, so that, taking the emigration of 1881- 
 1890 as a standard, it will be found that emigration from 
 Norway has not increased as fast as her population. 
 
 It will be remembered that the majority of the Scandina- 
 vian emigrants came from agricultural districts. One half 
 of the Norwegians who came to the United States before 
 1900 were engaged in agricultural pursuits. Since the 
 opportunity eventually to secure a homestead in the United 
 States is gone, the Norwegian agricultural laborer who is 
 dissatisfied with his condition must seek employment in 
 industry. And here the development of the Norwegian 
 industry offers him many an opportunity at home. The 
 recent industrial progress of Norway can be gauged by the 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table 9, pp. 66-96. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 203 
 
 fact that from 1897 to 1908 the quantity of horsepower used 
 increased 146.5 per cent. The average number of wage- 
 earners reduced to the basis of 300 working days per year, 
 increased during the same period 45 per cent, while the 
 total population increased during the same period only 9 
 per cent. 1 The rapid development of home industry ab- 
 sorbed a portion of the agricultural surplus population 
 which under former conditions might have found an outlet 
 in emigration. 
 
 E. Denmark 
 
 The total immigration from Denmark to the United 
 States up to and including 1910 numbered only a quarter 
 of a million, distributed as follows : 
 
 TABLE 59. 
 
 IMMIGRATION FROM DENMARK TO THE UNITED STATES, l82O-I9IO. a 
 
 Period Number 
 
 Up to 1880 53,774 
 
 1881-1890 88,132 
 
 1891-1900 50,231 
 
 1901-1910 65,285 
 
 Total 257,422 
 
 While immigration was greater during the last ten-year 
 period than during the preceding, yet it did not reach the 
 high level of 1881-1890. Since nearly one half of all Danes 
 in the United States in 1900 were engaged in agricultural 
 pursuits, the decrease of Danish immigration to the United 
 States might have some relation to the decline in the demand 
 for farm help in the United States. 
 
 On the other hand, the last fifteen years of the nineteenth 
 century "witnessed a great improvement in the condition 
 of life all round of the Danish peasant farmer." 3 Among 
 
 1 Statistigue Industrielle pour Vannee ipo8, editee par V office des Assu- 
 rances de I'Etat, pp. 18*, 230*, Kristiania, 1911. 
 
 'Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 66-96, 176-204. 
 
 3 Erik Givskov, "Peasant Farming in Denmark," The Economic 
 Journal, vol. viii (1903), p. 646. 
 
204 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the causes of that improvement, the most important one 
 is the rapid spread of co-operation in all branches of farming. 
 The first co-operative creamery was established in 1882. 
 According to a special census taken in 1906, there were 
 1068 such creameries whose membership embraced 82.3 
 per cent of all dairy farms. The co-operative creameries 
 controlled 93 per cent of the total milk production of the 
 country. The first co-operative association of exporters 
 of eggs was established in 1890. In 1906 there were 790 
 such associations with a membership of over 50,000 farmers, 
 who owned in the aggregate over 1,900,000 hens. There 
 were in 1905, thirty-two co-operative slaughter houses with 
 a membership of 63,000 farmers who owned one half of all 
 the swine of the country. x As a result, the export of agri- 
 cultural products from Denmark increased sixfold in twenty 
 years, viz., from an annual average of 49,000,000 crowns 3 
 in 1881-1885 to 313,000,000 crowns in 1901-1905. 3 
 
 The progress of agriculture has turned Denmark into a 
 country of immigration. Considerable numbers of Polish 
 peasants come during every agricultural season to work on 
 the farms in Denmark; in 1907, their number was 625 1, 4 
 which was equal to three fourths of the average annual 
 emigration of the period 1881-1890. 
 
 The manufacturing industries of the country have also 
 made progress. The total horsepower used in manufactures 
 increased 156 per cent from 1897 to 1906. The number of 
 wage-earners increased 15.4 per cent, while the population 
 increased only 3.5 per cent from 1901 to 1906, i. e., about n 
 per cent in nine years. 5 The industrial progress of Den- 
 
 * Danmarks Statistik. Landbrugets Andelsvirk somhed. Udgivet at 
 Statens Statistiske Bureau, 1906, pp. 8, 20, 24, 41, 43, 51, 67, 69. 
 
 3 1 crown = 26.8 cents. 
 
 Danemark, Precis de Statistique, 1907, pp. 14-15. 
 
 * Statistique de Danemark, Annuaire Statistique, 1908, p. 129, Table 
 98. 
 
 * Danemark, Precis de Statistique, 1907, p. 13. British Statistical 
 Abstract for the Principal and other Foreign Countries, No. XXXV., pp. 
 8. 10. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 205 
 
 mark encouraged organization among wage-earners. In 
 1908, 60 per cent of all industrial workers in Denmark 
 were organized. 1 
 
 The improvement of the condition of the Danish people 
 within the last twenty-five years is sufficient to account for 
 the decrease of emigration from that country, irrespective 
 of the immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe to 
 the United States. 
 
 F. Sweden 
 
 The emigration movement from Sweden for the past 
 half -century is classified by country of destination in the 
 following table : 
 
 TABLE 60. 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE EMIGRATION FROM SWEDEN BY DESTINATION, 
 (THOUSANDS), 1861-1908.' 
 
 Period 
 
 To non-European 
 countries 
 
 To European 
 countries 
 
 1861-1870 
 
 8. 9 
 
 34 
 
 1871-1880 
 
 IO.I 
 
 4.9 
 
 1881-1890 
 
 324 
 
 5-2 
 
 1891-1900 
 
 20.4 
 
 4.2 
 
 1901-1908 
 
 22.6 
 
 3-4 
 
 Emigration from Sweden, after reaching its highest point 
 in 1881-1890, began to decline. The fact to be noted is 
 that this declining tendency affected alike emigration 
 over-sea as well as to European countries. The probable 
 causes of the decline of each movement must be examined 
 separately. 
 
 A study of the sources of Swedish emigration shows that 
 the greater part of it came from rural districts, but the 
 
 1 Handworterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, vol. iv., p. 1210. 
 a Compiled from Gustav Sundbdrg's Ekonomisk-Statistisk Beskrifning 
 tifver Sveriges Olika Landsdelar, 1910, p. 95, Table 45. 
 
206 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 general decline of the movement did not affect the urban 
 and the rural districts in the same degree. The difference 
 appears from the following figures : 
 
 TABLE 61. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL EMIGRATION FROM CITIES AND RURAL DISTRICTS OF 
 
 SWEDEN (THOUSANDS), 1 88 1-1907.* 
 
 Period 
 
 Prom rural 
 districts 
 
 From cities 
 
 Total 
 
 1881-1890 
 1891-1900 
 1901-1907 
 
 304 
 I8. 7 
 21.3 
 
 7.2 
 6.0 
 6.4 
 
 37-6 
 24.7 
 27.7 
 
 We find that the decline of the total emigration is due to 
 the decline of emigration from the rural districts. A 
 comparison of the last two tables further shows that the 
 decrease of the average rural emigration from 1881-1890 
 to 1901-1907 is approximately equal to the decrease of the 
 average emigration to non-European countries during the 
 same period. If it is remembered that 30.2 per cent of 
 the Swedes who had settled in the United States in the past 
 century were engaged in agriculture and that during the 
 last twenty years the direction of Scandinavian immigration 
 to the United States turned from the West to the East, the 
 reason of the decline of emigration from the rural districts 
 of Sweden will be apparent: the United States no longer 
 holds out to the Swedish peasant the hope of becoming a 
 farmer. The Swedish peasant who is dissatisfied with his 
 surroundings must look for industrial employment. And 
 he finds that there are ample opportunities in Sweden 
 which attract immigrants from foreign countries. 
 
 A comparison of the emigration from Sweden to other 
 European countries with the immigration to Sweden from 
 those countries brings out the jact that during the past 
 decade the balance for the first time turned in favor of 
 Sweden: 
 
 * Sundbarg, loc. tit., p. 13, Table 17 (computed). 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 207 
 
 TABLE 62. 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE EMIGRATION FROM SWEDEN TO OTHER EUROPEAN 
 COUNTRIES AND IMMIGRATION TO SWEDEN FROM OTHER EUROPEAN 
 
 COUNTRIES (THOUSANDS), 1 881-1908. x 
 
 Annual average 
 
 Emigration 
 
 Immigration 
 
 Net immigration ( +) 
 or emigration ( ) 
 
 1881-1890 
 1891-1900 
 1901-1908 
 
 5-2 
 4.2 
 
 34 
 
 2.9 
 
 3-1 
 4.1 
 
 -2.3 
 I.I 
 
 + -7 
 
 It appears from Table 62 that while emigration from 
 Sweden to other European countries has been decreasing 
 from decade to decade, immigration to Sweden from those 
 countries has been on the increase. The net result of these 
 movements during the last period was a slight surplus of 
 immigration over emigration. Evidently economic opportu- 
 nities in Sweden must have sufficiently improved to attract 
 more foreigners while fewer Swedish people left the country. 
 
 The industrial progress of Sweden is contemporaneous 
 with the recent development of hydraulic and hydro-electric 
 engineering, which has harnessed the water power furnished 
 in abundance by her mountains. More than one half of 
 her motive power used in 1907 was derived from water 
 power, either directly or in the form of electric current 
 generated by water power. The increase in the use of 
 water power since 1896 amounted to 134 per cent. 2 As an 
 index of Sweden's industrial advance since the time when 
 her emigration was at its highest level, may be used the 
 production of iron ore, which increased from an annual 
 average of 900,000 tons in 1881-1890 to an average of more 
 than 3,500,000 in 1901-1905, i. e., nearly fourfold. 3 
 
 1 Sundbarg, loc. cit. t pp. 95-96, Tables 45-46. 
 
 a Out of a total of 607,000 horse-power used for driving machinery or 
 generating electric power, 330,000 was water power. Sveriges Officiella 
 Statistik. Fabriker och Handtverk, 1907, pp. xxix. and 118. 
 
 *Eli F. Heckscher, Till Belysning af Jdrnvdgarnas Betydelse for 
 Sveriges Ekonomiska Utveckling, p. 91. 
 
208 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The number of wage-earners in Swedish factories in- 
 creased from 202,000 in 1896 to 303,000 in 1907, i. e., at the 
 rate of 50 per cent in eleven years. l The growth of Swedish 
 industries far outran the increase of her population. The 
 factories offered employment to an average of 9000 new 
 hands annually, which was approximately equal to the 
 decrease in the annual average emigration from 1881-1890 
 to 1901-1908. 
 
 To what extent the wage-earners of Sweden have im- 
 proved the opportunities of the industrial situation, is 
 shown by the rapid progress of organization of labor and 
 the spread of collective bargaining. The total membership 
 of labor organizations increased from 50,000 in 1900 to 
 260,000 in 1908. The proportion of organized workers to 
 the total number of industrial wage-earners was estimated 
 at 45 per cent. 2 A highly instructive account of the 
 progress of collective bargaining is given in a Swedish 
 government report, from which the following is condensed. 3 
 
 About one half of the total number of wage-earners were 
 employed in establishments which had adopted the system 
 of collective bargaining. In the coal mines, sugar factories, 
 and potteries collective bargaining was practically the 
 general rule. In trade and transportation nearly all the 
 employees of private telephone companies, about 90 per 
 cent of all employees of electric street railways, and 66 per 
 cent of the employees on private steam railways were 
 working under collective trade agreements. In the build- 
 ing trades about three fourths of the total number and in 
 the factories and hand trades about one half were employed 
 under the same system. The principal industries where 
 collective bargaining has been adopted and the percentage 
 of the total number of wage-earners affected in each of 
 them are given in the following table : 
 
 1 Sveriges Officiella Statistik. Fabriker och Handtoerk, 1907, p. xxviii. 
 There are no comparable figures prior to 1896. 
 
 2 Handworterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, vol. iv, p. 1211. 
 
 3 Kollektivaftal A ngaenda Arbets-och Loneforhdllenden i Sverige (Stock, 
 holm, 1910), pp. 246-249. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 209 
 
 TABLE 63. 
 
 PER CENT OF WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED UNDER THE SYSTEM OF COL. 
 LECTIVE BARGAINING IN THE PRINCIPAL INDUSTRIES OF SWEDEN. 
 
 Printing 93 
 
 Fertilizers 82 
 
 Rubber 82 
 
 Matches 79 
 
 Tobacco manufactures 75 
 
 Collieries 71 
 
 Machinery .' 68 
 
 Jewelry 63 
 
 Cabinet making 47 
 
 Glass 47 
 
 Iron and steel 44 
 
 Leather 42 
 
 Textiles 35 
 
 In all of these industries [says the official report] it is chiefly the 
 large-scale establishments that have adopted collective bargaining, 
 whereas those establishments, where it is absent, generally belong to the 
 small-scale industry. Whenever a trust or a combine is organized in an 
 industry, collective labor agreements generally comprise a greater 
 number of factories within, than without the combination. 
 
 A noteworthy feature of these trade agreements is the 
 provision for compensation in cases of work accidents which 
 are not within the law of 1901 . Provisions of this character 
 are found in 1313 agreements affecting 67 per cent of the 
 total number of wage-earners coming under the operation 
 of this system. 
 
 It will not be disputed that the Slav and Italian immi- 
 grants to the United States are not responsible for the utili- 
 zation of the water power supply of the Scandinavian 
 mountain range, with the resulting industrial upheaval 
 which created a lively demand for labor in Sweden. That 
 nevertheless the immigration of unskilled laborers from 
 Sweden to the United States continues and grows, is the 
 best evidence that many of them consider the opportunities 
 in the United States superior to those which are open to 
 them at home. 
 
 G. The United Kingdom 
 Emigrants from the British Isles enjoy a great advantage 
 
210 Immigration and Labor 
 
 over those of all other nations in that the main fields of 
 modern immigration are controlled by English-speaking 
 peoples. An Englishman or an Irishman is equally at 
 home in the United States, in Canada, Australia, New 
 Zealand, and South Africa. The recent development of 
 those countries has naturally attracted a part of the emigra- 
 tion from Great Britain and Ireland. Furthermore, the 
 policy of restriction adopted in Australia, New Zealand, 
 and South Africa has conferred a special privilege upon 
 immigrants of British nationality. 
 
 On the other hand, the governments of Canada and 
 Australia are making systematic efforts to induce immigra- 
 tion from the mother country. x Contract laborers may be 
 freely imported into Canada, as well as into Australia. 
 Salaried agents of the Dominion government are stationed 
 in the large cities of Great Britain to promote emigration 
 to Canada. A bonus of i is paid to the booking agent on 
 each ticket to Canada sold to a British subject who is 
 engaged in the occupation of farmer, farm laborer, gar- 
 dener, stableman, carter, railway surface man, navvy, or 
 miner, and who signifies his intention to follow farming or 
 railway construction work in Canada. 2 Not content with 
 the work of regular immigration agents, Canada has been 
 sending agricultural delegates to Great Britain. The 
 Salvation Army is also utilized as an agency to promote 
 emigration to Canada, and grants of money are made to the 
 Army for that purpose. Canada annually receives a consid- 
 erable number of English immigrants, who have been sent by 
 private or state aid from the mother country. 3 Canada also 
 encourages the immigration of poor and homeless British 
 children to her borders. This immigration is chiefly recruit- 
 ed from the orphan or industrial homes of the British Isles. 4 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 2, pp. 607-631. 
 Ibid., pp. 607-608. 
 
 * In 1907, 12,336 persons were sent to Canada by London charitable 
 societies alone. 
 
 It is officially estimated that during the last 50 years nearly 60,000 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 211 
 
 The Australian government furnishes land to settlers at 
 a nominal price payable in small installments. Moreover, 
 in all the states except Tasmania, allowances are made to 
 settlers for improving their holdings. By way of further 
 inducements, the states pay the passage, wholly or in part, 
 of immigrants from the United Kingdom whose purpose it 
 is to settle on the land or to engage in farming or other work 
 of a similar nature. Assistance is also offered to domestic 
 servants and other persons who can satisfy the Australian 
 agent in London that they would make desirable settlers in 
 Australia. The policy of assisting immigration has been 
 pursued by the several states of Australia for a greater 
 part of the time since their settlement. According to 
 official information 653,698 state-aided immigrants have 
 been admitted to the Australian states. x 
 
 That all these efforts should have diverted from the 
 United States a part of the British emigration was inevi- 
 table, irrespective of any causes originating in the United 
 States. As shown in a preceding chapter, the rise of land 
 values in the United States and the agricultural opportuni- 
 ties of the Canadian Northwest have, during the past 
 decade, resulted in an emigration of American farmers to 
 Canada. Withal, it is a noteworthy fact that the move- 
 ment to the United States has been affected less than is 
 generally imagined. 
 
 Compared with the annual average for the period 1880- 
 1889, emigration from Great Britain and Ireland to the 
 United States has considerably declined. But as appears 
 from Table 64 the decade 1880-1889 cannot be taken as a 
 standard for comparison. The only period approaching it 
 was the decade 1850-1859, when over a million people 
 emigrated from Ireland. 2 Eliminating the two exceptional 
 
 juvenile immigrants have been transported from the British Isles to 
 Canada. From 1901 to 1909, inclusive, 19,034 of this class were sent 
 to Canada. 
 
 *Ibid., pp. 631-635. 
 
 a Census of Ireland, igoi, p. 168, Table 41. 
 
212 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 decades, we find that during the twenty-year period 1890- 
 1909, 2,425,000 immigrants came from Great Britain and 
 Ireland to the United States as against 2,254,000 in 1860- 
 1879. < 
 
 TABLE 64. 
 
 NUMBER OF EMIGRANTS FROM THE UNITED KINGDOM, BY DESTINATION 
 
 (THOUSANDS), 1840-1909. 
 
 
 
 
 Destination 
 
 
 
 Period 
 
 United States 
 
 North 
 American 
 Colonies 
 
 Australia, 
 New Zealand, 
 and 
 South Africa 
 
 Other 
 countries 
 
 Total 
 
 1840-1849 
 
 912 
 
 4 28 
 
 127 
 
 27 
 
 1495 
 
 1850-1859 
 
 631 
 
 259 
 
 499 
 
 52 
 
 2440 
 
 1860-1869 
 
 179 
 
 145 
 
 286 
 
 60 
 
 I 670 
 
 1870-1879 
 
 074 
 
 184. 
 
 296 
 
 IOO 
 
 1554 
 
 1880-1889 
 
 7 28 
 
 300 
 
 376 
 
 164 
 
 2568 
 
 1890-1899 
 
 196 
 
 191 
 
 234 
 
 171 
 
 1792 
 
 1900-1909 
 
 230 
 
 7 06 
 
 477 
 
 300 
 
 2612 
 
 The number of English and Irish immigrants since 1890 
 who found the conditions in the United States attractive 
 was 8500 in excess of the annual average for the period 
 1860-1879 preceding the "new immigration." 
 
 To be sure, the figures of gross immigration alone are not 
 conclusive, as they conceal many unsuccessful ventures 
 ending in a return movement to the home country. In 
 Table 65 are therefore presented the figures of net emigra- 
 tion from the British Isles by countries of destination since 
 1895, when immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 to the United States for the first time outran the "old 
 immigration." 
 
 1 The Civil War reduced emigration from the United Kingdom to the 
 United States only in 1861 and 1862. During the next three years the 
 number of emigrants bound for the United States rose to a higher level 
 than that of 1855-1860 or 1874-1879. See Appendix, Table XV. 
 
 See Appendix, Table XV. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 213 
 
 TAB^E 65. 
 
 NET EMIGRATION OF BRITISH SUBJECTS FROM THE UNITED KINGDOM 
 BY COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION (THOUSANDS), 1895-1909. 
 
 
 Destination 
 
 
 British Possessions 
 
 Foreign Countries 
 
 
 Year 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 a 
 
 ended 
 
 3 
 
 "2*3 
 
 O^ 
 
 j3 
 
 
 f'" >: 
 
 
 
 
 g 
 
 March 31 
 
 Is 
 
 Sg 
 
 oz 
 
 5 
 
 
 
 .? 
 
 
 H 
 
 
 II 
 
 H 
 
 Australia 
 New Zeal 
 
 Cape of C 
 Hope and . 
 
 Si 
 
 V BJ 
 
 i 
 
 i 
 1 
 i 
 
 i! 
 la 
 
 H 
 
 1 
 
 1895 
 
 6 
 
 I 
 
 12 
 
 I 
 
 20 
 
 56 
 
 
 56 
 
 76 
 
 1896 
 
 6 
 
 I 
 
 IO 
 
 2 
 
 19 
 
 40 
 
 i 
 
 41 
 
 60 
 
 1897 
 
 6 
 
 4 
 
 6 
 
 3 
 
 19 
 
 31 
 
 i 
 
 32 
 
 51 
 
 1898 
 
 8 
 
 4 
 
 6 
 
 2 
 
 2O 
 
 29 
 
 
 29 
 
 49 
 
 1899 
 I9OO 
 
 8 
 8 
 
 8 
 
 -6 
 
 7 
 
 I 
 2 
 
 7 
 23 
 
 39 
 
 48 
 
 
 39 
 
 48 
 
 46 
 71 
 
 1901 
 
 7 
 
 6 
 
 9 
 
 3 
 
 25 
 
 46 
 
 i 
 
 47 
 
 72 
 
 1902 
 1903 
 
 15 
 46 
 
 4 
 4 
 
 28 
 28 
 
 3 
 3 
 
 I? 
 
 11 
 
 i 
 
 
 1 02 
 147 
 
 1904 
 
 51 
 
 5 
 
 i 
 
 4 
 
 59 
 
 67 
 
 i 
 
 68 
 
 127 
 
 1905 
 
 63 
 
 7 
 
 3 
 
 4 
 
 77 
 
 6l 
 
 i 
 
 62 
 
 139 
 
 1906 
 
 
 10 
 
 -3 
 
 7 
 
 105 
 
 86 
 
 4 
 
 90 
 
 195 
 
 1907 
 
 117 
 
 14 
 
 ~5 
 
 5 
 
 131 
 
 IOO 
 
 4 
 
 104 
 
 235 
 
 1908 
 
 42 
 
 21 
 
 -5 
 
 i 
 
 59 
 
 3* 
 
 i 
 
 32 
 
 
 1909 
 
 52 
 
 25 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 82 
 
 56 
 
 2 
 
 58 
 
 140 
 
 As appears from Diagram XVI, where the same figures 
 are shown graphically, the curves representing net emigra- 
 tion to the United States and to British possessions exhibit 
 a tendency to rise and fall together. From 1898 to 1907 
 the net immigration to the United States was steadily rising 
 with slight deviations in the years ended March 31, 1901, 
 and 1905, i. e., in the two presidential years. Since the 
 latter year, the immigration countries of the British Empire 
 have drawn and held more immigrants than the United 
 
 1 Computed from Statistical Abstract of the United Kingdom, No. 
 57, PP. 363-364. Tables 117, 118, 119. 
 
 "Includes 22,719 passengers from 1895 to 1907 whose nationality is 
 not specified. 
 
214 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 States, but the net immigration to the United States also 
 increased. The drop in 1908 affected the net immigration 
 to Canada as much as that to the United States. In 1909 
 the net immigration to the United States exhibited a greater 
 increase, both absolute and relative, than the net immigra- 
 
 DlAGRAM XVI. 
 
 XVI. Net emigration from the United Kingdom by destination, 1895-1909. 
 
 tion to all British possessions. Obviously, conditions in 
 the United States, notwithstanding immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, compared favorably with 
 those in other immigration countries. 
 
 Another factor determining the volume of emigration, 
 that must not be lost sight of, is the improvement of living 
 conditions in Great Britain. In the first place, there has 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 215 
 
 been a decrease in the cost of living. Measuring the cost 
 of living by wholesale prices and taking the Board of Trade 
 index number for 1900 as 100, official estimates put the cost 
 of living in 1878-1887 at 119.5 and in 1898-1907 at 97.8. 
 At the same time the rates of wages have increased. 1 An 
 estimate of the course of average real wages in the second 
 half of the nineteenth century is reproduced in the fol- 
 lowing table: 
 
 TABLE 66. 
 
 AVERAGE REAL WAGES IN GREAT BRITAIN, 1850-1900. 
 
 Year Per Cent 
 
 1850 50 
 
 i860 55 
 
 1870 60 
 
 1880 70 
 
 1890 84 
 
 1895 93 
 
 1900 100 
 
 During the decade 1850-1859, when immigration from 
 the British Isles to the United States reached its maximum, 
 relative to population, and the decade 1880-1889, when it 
 reached its numerical maximum, the real wages averaged 
 from 50 to 55 per cent and from 70 to 84 per cent, respec- 
 tively, of the wages of 1900. The improvement is sufficient 
 to account for the reduction in the rate of emigration from 
 the United Kingdom. 
 
 H. Ireland 
 
 Emigration from Ireland to all countries reached its 
 maximum during the decade ended March 31, 1861, and 
 has since declined. The tide rose again during the '8o's, 
 in the turbulent years of the Irish Land League agitation, 
 and once more during the past decade, but not as high 
 as the water-mark reached in 1852-1861. The figures are 
 given in Table 67 below. 
 
 1 Beveridge, loc. cit., p. 9. 
 
 a Ibid., quoting: A. L. Bowley, National Progress in Wealth and 
 Trade, p. 33. 
 
2i6 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 67. 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE EMIGRATION FROM IRELAND, MAY I, 1 85 1, 
 TO MARCH 31, IQOS. s 
 
 Years ended March 3 x (Thousand*) 
 
 1852-1861 115 
 
 1862-1871 77 
 
 1872-1881 62 
 
 1882-1891 77 
 
 1892-1901 43 
 
 1902-1908 50 
 
 There are no accurate statistics showing the distribution 
 of Irish emigrants by destination previous to 1876. The 
 subsequent years 1876-1908 for which such statistics are 
 available may be divided with respect to the racial composi- 
 tion of the immigration to the United States into two 
 periods of nearly equal length; previous to 1891 the races 
 of Northern and Western Europe furnished the bulk of the 
 immigrants, whereas during the more recent period the 
 races of Southern and Eastern Europe became the pre- 
 dominant element among them. The figures are presented 
 in Table 67 on page 216. 
 
 Two facts are worthy of note in the following compara- 
 tive table: first, that the decline of emigration from Ireland 
 has affected the movement to other countries, as well as to 
 the United States, and second, that the proportion of Irish 
 emigrants destined to the United States during the period 
 of the great influx of immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe was higher than in 1876-1890, when immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe was negligible. 
 
 That the "new immigration" to the United States was 
 not the cause of the decline of Irish emigration is clear from 
 the fact that the decline had set in as early as 1861-1870, 
 at least twenty years before the immigrants from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe became sufficiently numerous to attract 
 
 1 The enumeration of emigrants fronTlrish ports did not commence 
 until May I, 1851. 
 
 Census of Ireland, 1901, Part II., p. 168, Table 41. Statistical 
 Abstract of the United Kingdom, No. 56, p. 365. 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 217 
 
 notice. The conclusion suggested by the statistics of Irish 
 emigration is that there must have been forces at work to 
 reduce the number of Irish seeking a better home than their 
 native country. 
 
 TABLE 68. 
 
 ANNUAL AVERAGE EMIGRATION FROM IRELAND, BY DESTINATION, 
 I876-I908. 1 
 
 
 To the United States 
 
 
 Period 
 
 
 To other countries 
 (thousands) 
 
 Total 
 (thousands) 
 
 (Thousands) 
 
 Per cent of total 
 
 1876-1890' 
 
 69 
 
 50 
 
 72 
 
 19 
 
 1891-19083 
 
 46 
 
 38 
 
 83 
 
 8 
 
 The change in the economic condition of the Irish people 
 since the '8o's may be summed up in the following words of 
 Mr. Dillon: 
 
 The wretched land system was responsible for most of the misery 
 which the poor suffered. Successive land purchases are gradually 
 restoring the worse than homeless tenants to the land, and each family 
 so restored becomes decently prosperous, because for the first time there 
 is offered a chance to make a living. . . . The helpless, hopeless 
 tenants and the evicted families are being made independent. . . 
 The thousands who have been put in the way of making decent farms 
 and homes have become hopeful and self-reliant instead of despairing. 
 . . . Those families who were struggling against starvation on the 
 rocky hillsides are now cultivating fertile fields. 4 
 
 That this is not mere rhetoric a few figures will show. 
 
 1 Computed from the following sources: Census of Ireland, i88I, 
 Part II., p. 74; 1891, Part II., p. 74; 1901, Part II., p. 74; 1901, Part II., 
 Table 41, p. 168; Statistical Abstract of the United Kingdom, No. 48, p. 
 255; No. 56, p. 365; Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table 
 9, pp. 76-92. 
 
 3 Calendar years. 
 
 3 Total emigration from Ireland for 17^ years, from January i, 1891, 
 to March 31, 1908; immigration to the United States for 17 years from 
 January I, 1891, to December 31, 1908. 
 
 ^ Hugh Sutherland: Ireland Yesterday and To-day (1909), p. 108. 
 
218 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Under the operation of the several purchase acts passed 
 since 1885, more than 214,000 tenants have been enabled 
 to buy their land with the assistance of the government. 1 
 This number is equal to one third of all families enumerated 
 in rural areas at the census of 1901 . 3 Under the provisions 
 of the Wyndham Act of 1903, the government is authorized 
 to expend $800,000,000 in loans to tenants at 3% per cent 
 for the purchase of land, which is to be paid for in 68 J^ 
 years. 3 Furthermore, the rent of the tenants has been 
 substantially reduced by law, to which must be added the 
 creation of a legal interest of a marketable character, 
 together with a chance of further abatements in the future. 4 
 
 Other legislation has been enacted for the benefit of 
 agricultural laborers. "County authorities are able to 
 borrow government funds for the erection of decent sani- 
 tary dwellings, which rent for I shilling a week. Nearly 
 50,000 of these neat cottages have been erected." 5 
 
 Another factor which has materially contributed to the 
 improvement of the condition of the Irish farmers has been 
 the co-operative movement which dates from 1889. In 
 1903 there were more than 800 co-operative societies with 
 an aggregate membership of 80,000 farmers. 6 Perhaps, the 
 most important among these societies are the co-operative 
 agricultural banks, which in the language of Sir Horace 
 Plunkett "perform the apparent miracle of giving sol- 
 vency to a community composed almost entirely of in- 
 solvent individuals." 7 There are more than 200 of these 
 banks which lend money to farmers at 5 or 6 per cent per 
 annum for agricultural improvements. 8 
 
 The improvement of the condition of the tenants has 
 
 * Ibid., p. 114. 
 
 3 The Census of Ireland, General Report, Table 49, p. 173. 
 
 * Sutherland, loc. cit., p. 114. 
 
 C. F. Bastable: "Some Features of the Economic Movement in 
 Ireland, 1880-1900," Economic Journal, 4901, No. xi., pp. 33, 39. 
 s Sutherland, loc. cit., p. 183. 
 
 6 Horace Plunkett : Ireland in the New Century, p. 192. 
 
 7 Ibid., p. 195. 8 Ibid., pp. 192, 197* 
 
From Northern and Western Europe 219 
 
 affected the labor market; there has been a substantial 
 gain in the real wages of farm laborers. 1 
 
 The improvement of the living conditions of the Irish 
 people is reflected in the statistics of housing accom- 
 modations. The census of Ireland divides all houses into 
 four classes: "In the lowest of the four classes are com- 
 prised houses built of mud or perishable material, having 
 only one room and window; in the third a better descrip- 
 tion of house, varying from one to four rooms and windows; 
 in the second what might be considered a good farmhouse, 
 having from five to nine rooms and windows; and in the 
 first class all houses of a better description than the 
 preceding." 2 
 
 TABLE 69. 
 
 FAMILIES OCCUPYING EACH CLASS OF INHABITED HOUSES IN RURAL 
 AREAS OF IRELAND, l86l~I9OI.3 
 
 
 Number (thousands) 
 
 Per cent 
 
 
 Census 
 
 
 
 
 period 
 
 I 
 
 II 
 
 III 
 
 IV 
 
 I 
 
 II 
 
 III 
 
 IV 
 
 Total 
 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 class 
 
 
 1861 
 
 29 
 
 291 
 
 471 
 
 90 
 
 3-3 
 
 33-0 
 
 53-5 
 
 IO.2 
 
 IOO 
 
 1881 
 
 36 
 
 309 
 
 356 
 
 39 
 
 4.9 
 
 41.7 
 
 48.1 
 
 54 
 
 IOO 
 
 1891 
 
 4 
 
 332 
 
 288 
 
 20 
 
 
 48.9 
 
 42.4 
 
 2.9 
 
 IOO 
 
 1901 
 
 41 
 
 353 
 
 230 
 
 9 
 
 6.4 
 
 55-8 
 
 36.4 
 
 1.4 
 
 IOO 
 
 While housing conditions in Ireland to-day are still 
 far from ideal, yet they show evidence of very real improve- 
 ment, compared with the days when emigration from 
 Ireland was at its maximum. The number of one-room 
 huts with one window, built of mud or other material of 
 the same class, decreased since 1861 from 90,000 to 9,000. 
 In 1 86 1, there were but one in three houses that might be 
 considered good farm houses; forty years later about the 
 same proportion fell below that definition. 
 
 1 Bastable, loc. tit., p. 38. 
 
 J Census of Ireland, General Report for 1901, p. II. 
 
 Computed from the Census of Ireland .General Report, Table 49, 
 
220 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The results of the census of 1911 have as yet not been 
 published. In Mr. Dillon's opinion, "Ireland has made 
 more progress in the last ten years than during the previous 
 two hundred years. " * Is it reasonable to assume that the 
 same rate of emigration from Ireland could be maintained 
 to-day as half a century ago? 
 
 /. Conclusion 
 
 To sum up the preceding review of economic conditions 
 in the countries of Northern and Western Europe, it is 
 not because the "new immigration" has had an unfavorable 
 effect upon labor conditions in the United States, but 
 because those countries have become better homes for their 
 citizens, that fewer of them are nowadays coming to the 
 United States. If this country is to have immigration, 
 it will have to come from other sources. To be sure, it 
 may be argued that this country has no further need of 
 immigration in general and can therefore dispense with 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe. Be it as 
 it may, it is a fallacy to assume that they could be replaced 
 by potential immigration from Northern and Western 
 Europe. 
 
 1 Sutherland, loc. cit. t p. 108. 
 
CHAPTER IX 
 
 RACE SUICIDE 
 
 IT cannot be seriously disputed that the great immigration 
 of recent years has come in response to a demand for 
 labor in the United States. Industrial progress and im- 
 provement of the condition of the wage-earners and farmers 
 in the countries of Northern and Western Europe rendered 
 the supply of immigrant labor from those sources inadequate. 
 Without the immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, the rapid industrial expansion of the past decade 
 would have been impossible. But it seems to the Immigra- 
 tion Commission, that "there is ground for argument or 
 speculation" that "less immigration of a character tending 
 to keep down wages and working conditions might have 
 been attended by a larger natural increase among the native- 
 born portion of the population." 1 
 
 This theory, originated by Gen. Francis A. Walker, until 
 lately held unchallenged the field of economic and sociologi- 
 cal discussion. General Walker believed that immigration 
 had caused a decline in the birth-rate of the native American 
 population : 
 
 The American shrank from the industrial competition thus thrust 
 upon him. He was unwilling himself to engage in the lowest kind of 
 day-labor with these new elements of the population; he was even more 
 unwilling to bring sons and daughters into the world to enter into that 
 competition. Foreign immigration into this country has . . . amounted 
 not to a re-enforcement of our population, but to a replacement of 
 native by foreign stock. ... If the foreigners had not come, the native 
 element would long have filled the places the foreigners usurped. 3 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 494. 
 'Francis A. Walker: Discussions in Economics and Statistics, pp. 
 432-425. 
 
 Ml 
 
222 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 In proof of his theory, General Walker maintained that 
 the decline of the birth-rate 
 
 among Americans began at the very time when foreign immigration 
 first assumed considerable proportions; it showed itself first and in 
 the highest degree in those regions, in those States, and in the very 
 counties into which the foreigners most largely entered. It proceeded 
 for a long time in such a way as absolutely to offset the foreign arrivals, 
 so that in 1850, in spite of the incoming of two and a half millions of 
 foreigners during thirty years, our population differed by less than ten 
 thousand from the population which would have existed, according to 
 the previous rate of increase, without re-enforcement from abroad. 
 These three facts . . . constitute a statistical demonstration such as 
 is rarely attained in regard to the operation of any social or economic 
 force. 1 
 
 General Walker's statistical demonstration consisted in a 
 comparison of the census figures from 1820 to 1890 with a 
 calculation made by Elkanah Watson in 1815 on the basis 
 of the increase of population from 1790 to 1810. The 
 census figures for 1820-1850 closely coincided with Watson's 
 estimates. 2 Yet, whereas prior to 1820 immigration was 
 insignificant, from 1820 to 1850, 2,500,000 foreigners were 
 added to the population of the United States without in- 
 creasing it to any appreciable degree. The inference seemed 
 to be incontrovertible that the development of the natural 
 resources of the United States made provision for a fixed 
 population at every census, so that the two-and-a-half 
 million foreigners merely usurped the places of as many 
 unborn Americans. At every subsequent census Watson's 
 calculations proved to be overestimated, viz.: in 1860 by 
 over 300,000, in 1870 by 3,770,000, in 1880 by more than 
 
 1 Walker, loc. cit., p. 441. 
 * Ibid., pp. 120-122: 
 
 Year 
 
 Watson's estimates 
 
 The census 
 
 Difference 
 
 1820 
 1830 
 1840 
 1850 
 
 9.625,734 
 12,833,645 
 17,116,526 
 23,185,368 
 
 9,633,822 
 I2,866,O2O 
 
 17.069,453 
 23,191,876 
 
 -f 8,088 
 +32.375 
 -47.073 
 + 6,508 
 
Race Suicide 223 
 
 six millions, and in 1890 by over fourteen millions. Chief 
 among the social and economic causes of this shortage 
 compared with Watson's calculation was, according to 
 General Walker, "the access of vast hordes of foreign 
 immigrants bringing with them a standard of living at 
 which our own people revolted. " x The revolt assumed the 
 form of a strike of American parents against child-bearing. 
 This conclusion illustrates in a striking manner the effect 
 of a preconceived idea upon the reasoning ability of a 
 scientific writer. Twenty years before promulgating his 
 theory, General Walker had made light of Watson's pre- 
 dictions. Writing in 1873 on the results of the IX. Census 
 (1870), he dwelt upon the social change which 
 
 began when the people of the United States began to leave agricul- 
 tural for manufacturing pursuits; to turn from the country to the town; 
 to live in up-and-down houses. ... A close observer must discern causes 
 now working within the nation, which render it little less than absurd 
 longer to apply the former rates of growth to the computation of our 
 population at 1880, 1890, or 1900. ... It would be merely an attempt 
 at imposture to assume that numerical data exist for determining, 
 within eight or ten or twelve millions, the population of the country 
 thirty years from the date of the last census. As long as one simple 
 force was operating expansively upon a homogeneous people, within a 
 territory affording fertile lands beyond the ability of the existing popula- 
 tion to occupy, so long it was no miracle to predict with accuracy the 
 results of the census. But in the eddy and swirl of social and industrial 
 currents through which the nation is now passing, it is wholly impossible 
 to estimate the rate of its progress. 3 
 
 Still General Walker's later theory stands and falls with 
 Watson's predictions. 
 
 A reaction against that theory was led by Prof. Wal- 
 ter F. Willcox, in the Supplementary Analysis of the Results 
 of the XII. Census. Later, in a paper read at the an- 
 nual meeting of the American Statistical Association in 
 St. Louis in ipio, 3 Prof essor Willcox proved by an analysis 
 
 1 Walker, loc. tit., p. 426. 2 Ibid., p. 43. 
 
 * "The Change in the Proportion of Children in the United States" 
 etc., by W. F. Willcox : Quarterly Publications of the A merican Statistical 
 Association, March, 1911. 
 
224 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of population statistics "that the decrease in the proportion 
 of children began in the United States as early as i8io." x 
 The number of children under five years of age to one 
 hundred women of the child-bearing age decreased in 1810- 
 1830 by 9.9, and in 1880-1900 by 9.4. Thus the twenty- 
 year period of the recent immigration did not substantially 
 differ in this respect from the time when, according to Gen- 
 eral Walker himself, immigration had not affected the birth- 
 rate among native Americans. 
 
 Moreover, the declining birth-rate is a world-wide social 
 phenomenon of the present day. In the Australian Com- 
 monwealth, with her vast continent as yet unsettled and 
 practically no immigration, as well as in New Zealand, 
 "the decline of the birth-rate has probably been as rapid, " 
 says Professor Willcox, "as among native American stock." 2 
 
 The greater decline of the native birth-rate in those 
 sections and counties into which the foreigners most largely 
 enter, goes together with the growth of the urban popu- 
 lation. The percentage ratio of native white children of 
 native parentage under five years of age, to native women of 
 child-bearing age averaged in 1900 for cities with 25,000 
 inhabitants or over 29.6, and for smaller cities and rural 
 territory 52.2. The latter ratio, of course, is subject 
 to great variation, the limits being 76.7 in Louisiana and 
 29 . i in Massachusetts. 3 As indicated by these two extremes 
 
 1 Walker, loc. cit,, pp. 495-496. 
 
 ' Supplementary Analysis. XII. Census, p. 410. Carlton, loc. eii., 
 P- 347- 
 
 " So alarming has this phenomenon of the falling birth-rate become 
 in the Australian colonies, that in New South Wales a special govern- 
 mental commission has voluminously reported upon the subject. It is 
 estimated that there has been a decline of about one third in the fruit- 
 fulness of the people in fifteen years. New Zealand even complains of 
 the lack of children to fill her schools."-^- 4 'Race Progress and Immigra- 
 tion," by William Z. Ripley, Annals of the American Academy m of Politi- 
 cal and Social Science, vol. xxxiv., pp. 132-133. 
 
 Supplementary Analysis, XII. Census, Table XXII., p. 434. 
 
Per cent ratio of native white children under 5 years of age, born of 
 
 native mothers, to native white females 15 to 44 years of age in 
 
 cities of less than 25,000 inhabitants and rural territory, 1900. 
 
 UNDER 
 
 50 TO 60 ft 
 60% ScOVf.fi 
 
Race Suicide 
 
 225 
 
 the variation of the statistical average is to a great extent 
 purely arithmetical, being due to the heterogeneous charac- 
 ter of the settlements combined in this class; on the one 
 hand, there are the manufacturing towns of Massachusetts, 
 on the other, the purely agricultural settlements of Loui- 
 siana. The connection between the agricultural character 
 of the population of this class of settlements and the ratio 
 of native-born children to native women of child-bearing 
 age can be seen from Table 70 in which all States are 
 divided into four areas, according to the ratio of native- 
 born children under five, and the percentage of "farmers, 
 planters, and overseers" to the total number of bread- 
 winners for each group is given in a parallel column. 
 
 TABLE 70. 
 
 PER CENT RATIO OF NATIVE WHITE CHILDREN UNDER 5 TEARS OF AGE, 
 BORN OF NATIVE MOTHERS, TO NATIVE WHITE FEMALES, 15 TO 44 
 YEARS OF AGE, IN CITIES OF LESS THAN 25.OOO INHABITANTS AND 
 RURAL TERRITORY, AND PER CENT RATIO OF NATIVE WHITE MALE 
 FARMERS, PLANTERS, AND OVERSEERS TO THE TOT^L NUMBER OF 
 WHITE MALE BREADWINNERS, IQOO, BY AREAS COMPRISING STATES 
 AND TERRITORIES GROUPED ACCORDING TO RATIO OF CHILDREN, 
 1900. (THE STATES ARE SHOWN ON THE MAP FACING THE TABLE.) 
 
 Areas 
 
 Children 1 
 
 Farmers, etc.* 
 
 I 
 II 
 III 
 
 IV 
 
 Over 60 per cent 
 50 to 60 per cent 
 40 to 50 per cent 
 Under 40 per cent 
 
 6 7 .2 
 54-2 
 47-5 
 35-3 
 
 38.4 
 26.4 
 21.6 
 
 13.3 
 
 Continental United States 
 
 52.2 
 
 24.7 
 
 The preceding table clearly shows that the native birth- 
 rate declines with the percentage of farmers among the 
 
 * Supplementary Analysis, XII. Census, Table XXII, p. 434- 
 
 a Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 41, pp. 220 et seq. (computed). 
 
226 Immigration and Labor 
 
 native population. The rearing of children on a farm 
 requires less^ of the mother's time and attention than in the 
 city. Moreover, the child on a farm begins to work at an 
 earlier age than in the city. A numerous family on a farm 
 has the advantages of a co-operative group, whereas every 
 addition to the family of the wage-earner, or of the salaried 
 employee with a fixed income, tends to lower the family's 
 standard of living. 
 
 On the other hand, the decline of the birth-rate is uni- 
 versal among those classes which are scarcely, if at all, 
 affected by immigrant competition. This observation, 
 advanced by students in America and in England, 1 was 
 substantiated by the Report of the National Birth Rate 
 Commission on the declining birth-rate in the United 
 Kingdom. The results of its studies are summarized in 
 the following proposition: 
 
 Such statistical evidence as is available for establishing a comparison 
 of the birth-rate among the different social and pecuniary grades of 
 our population indicates that the better-to-do classes restrict more 
 closely the size of their families, and that even among certain of the 
 wage-earning classes the birth-rate varies inversely with the income. 1 
 
 Analyzing the interrelation between the declining birth- 
 rate and "the condition of the working-class," the Com- 
 mission concludes: 
 
 1 A. Lapthorn Smith: "Higher Education of Women and Race 
 Suicide," Popular Science Monthly, March, 1905, pp. .468, 470. Arthur 
 Newsholme: The Declining Birth-Rate , pp. 32, 33, 42-43. 
 
 2 The Declining Birth-Rate, Its Causes and Effects, p. 44. By way 
 of illustration, the statistics of births in 191 1, provided by the Registrar- 
 General for England and Wales are quoted in the table next following 
 (Ibid., p. 9). The returns were classified according to the occupation 
 of the father and summarized "in descending order of social grade." 
 The figures represent the ratio of births per 1 ,000 married males under 
 the age of 55. 
 
 Social Class Births per 7,000 
 
 1. Upper and middle class 1 19 
 
 2. Intermediate TV. 132 
 
 3. Skilled workmen 153 
 
 4. Intermediate class 158 
 
 5. Unskilled workmen 213 
 
Race Suicide 227 
 
 that every rise in the condition of the artisan tends at present to lower 
 the birth-rate in his class. Wherever political and social conditions 
 bring a man or a class into a position in which he hopes to rise or fears 
 to fall, the family will be restricted. That class of motives, which we 
 may blame as love of comfort, snobbishness, vulgar ambition, timorous- 
 ness, or praise as proper pride, desire for self-improvement, and 
 prudence, is the most potent cause of family restriction. 1 
 
 In relation to the United States, similar views were ex- 
 pressed by the late Dr. Billings as far back as 1893. It is 
 the desire of "the lower middle classes" to maintain "social 
 position," along with "the great increase in the use of 
 things which were formerly considered as luxuries, but 
 which now have become almost necessities" that accounts 
 in part for "the deliberate and voluntary avoidance or 
 prevention of child-bearing." 2 Still "the lower middle 
 classes" are scarcely affected by immigration. Their 
 standard of living is, as a rule, higher than that of the 
 wage-earner. Yet it is precisely this higher standard that 
 is productive of a "desire to have fewer children." All 
 speculation to the effect that an increase in the rate of 
 wages "might have been attended" in the past, or is likely 
 to be attended in the future, "by a larger natural increase 
 among the native-born portion of the population," has 
 accordingly no foundation of fact. 
 
 1 Ibid., pp. 41-42. 
 
 8 Supplementary Analysis, XII. Census, p. 410. 
 
CHAPTER X 
 
 . THE STANDARD OF LIVING. 
 
 A. Introductory 
 
 IN so far as immigration is an economic movement, it is 
 obvious that the immigrant's standard of living in his 
 home country must have been below the American standard. 
 This is as true of the old as of the new immigration. Those 
 immigrants only are an exception to this rule who seek to 
 escape from political or religious oppression. Its victims 
 are not confined to the poorer classes, but include people of 
 means and of standing in the community, whose standard 
 of living is often superior to that of the native American 
 mechanic. Since 1890, however, of all the races which have 
 come to this country, the Jews, the Poles, the Lithuanians, 
 the Russians, the Finns, and the Armenians, have 
 furnished the only immigrants of this class. As to all 
 others, it was just the higher standard of living F of the 
 American wage-earner that induced them, like most races 
 that preceded them, to emigrate to the United States. If 
 the lower standard of living to which the immigrant has 
 been accustomed at home tends to reduce the American 
 standard of living, then these effects of immigration must 
 have manifested themselves in the days of the Irish and 
 German immigration as much as to-day. At most there 
 may be only a difference of degree. That the standard of 
 living of the recent immigrant employed as an unskilled 
 laborer is lower than that of the native American mechanic 
 or of the older immigrant engaged in skilled work, is no new 
 
 228 
 
The Standard of Living 229 
 
 discovery. To prove, however, that the new immigrants 
 have introduced a lower standard of living, it is necessary 
 to show that the standard of living of the recent immigrants 
 employed as unskilled laborers is lower than that of the 
 Irish and German immigrants of past generations who were 
 doing the same grade of work, or of the native American 
 unskilled workers of the time before the Irish and German 
 immigration. The experts of the Immigration Commission, 
 however, have simply taken for granted that the standard 
 of living of the present-day American or Americanized 
 skilled mechanic is identical with that of the unskilled 
 laborer of the same racial stocks in the days before the new 
 immigration. This assumption is not borne out by Ameri- 
 can economic history. 
 
 The housing conditions of the foreign-born population 
 have been most dwelt upon in the discussion of the standard 
 of living of the immigrant, because they strike the eye of 
 the outsider. On this subject there are ample comparative 
 data. New York has always had more than its propor- 
 tionate share of newly arrived immigrants; its housing 
 problem, as affected by immigration, therefore, calls for 
 separate treatment. 
 
 B. Congestion in New York City 
 
 Overcrowding was recognized as a serious evil in New 
 York City as far back as 1834. A city inspector for that 
 year attributed the high rate of mortality to "the crowded 
 and filthy state" in which the population of New York 
 lived. 1 As the city was growing, the well-to-do residents 
 were moving northward and their old dwellings were let 
 to the poor. The traditional American one-family house 
 was adapted to the requirements of a population of inde- 
 pendent artisans and small shopkeepers, many of whom 
 were home-owners. With the growth of great cities and 
 the rise of land values, and with the development of a 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 452. 
 
230 Immigration and Labor 
 
 wage-earning class, the one-family house became the cause 
 of congestion in its worst form. The rental of such a house 
 was beyond the reach of the wage-earner. Each room was 
 let out to a separate family. Naturally, such improvised 
 dwellings lacked the most necessary accommodations. The 
 basement of the one-family house of the old type, formerly 
 used as a dining-room and kitchen, developed into a separate 
 cellar apartment. 
 
 Towards the middle of the '40*8 there had grown up in 
 New York a great "cellar population." A pen picture of 
 the condition of the cellars is given in a report on the Sani- 
 tary Condition of the Laboring Population^ which was 
 published in 1845: 
 
 The most offensive of all places of residence are the cellars. It is 
 almost impossible, when contemplating the circumstances and condi- 
 tions of the poor beings who inhabit these holes, to maintain the proper 
 degree of calmness requisite for a thorough inspection of their miseries 
 and sound judgment respecting them. You must descend to them; 
 you must feel the blast of foul air, as it meets your face on opening the 
 door; you must grope in the dark or hesitate until your eye becomes 
 accustomed to the gloomy place, to enable you to find your way through 
 the entry over the broken floor, the boards of which are protected from 
 your tread by a half inch of hard dirt; you must inhale the suffocating 
 vapor of the heated rooms; and in the dark, dim recesses endeavor to 
 find the inmates by the sound of their voices, or chance to see their 
 figures moving between you and the flickering light of a window, coated 
 with dirt and festooned with cobwebs or, if in search of an invalid, 
 take care that you do not fall full length upon the bed with her, by 
 stumbling against the rags and straw dignified by that name, lying 
 upon the floor, under the window, if window there is. 1 
 
 The occupants of these tenements were "principally 
 Irish and German " whose habits were described in 1837 as 
 "more or less filthy." An account of one of these houses, 
 in the rear of No. 49 Elizabeth Street, is given in an official 
 report of a city physician : 
 
 The front building, a small two-story frame house, was partly occu- 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 453. 
 
The Standard of Living 231 
 
 pied by the proprietor or lessee of the building as a liquor store and 
 partly sublet to several Irish families. A covered alleyway led to the 
 rear of the building. This was a double frame house of three stories 
 in height. It stood in the center of the yard, ranged next the fence, 
 where a number of pigsties and stables had surrounded the yard on three 
 sides. From the quantity of filth, liquid and otherwise, thus caused, 
 the ground, I suppose, had been rendered almost impassable, and to 
 remedy this, the yard had been completely boarded over so that the 
 earth could nowhere be seen. These boards were partially decayed, and 
 by a little pressure, even in dry weather, a thick, greenish, fluid could 
 be forced up through the crevices. 1 
 
 These evils were not confined, however, to the foreign- 
 bom population. The living conditions of the sewing 
 women, a large majority of whom were American-born, 
 were thus described by the New York Tribune, in the same 
 year 1 845: 
 
 These women generally "keep house" that is, they rent a single 
 room, or perhaps two small rooms, in the upper story of some poor, 
 ill-constructed, unventilated house in a filthy street, constantly kept so 
 by the absence of back yards and the neglect of the street inspector 
 where a sickening and deadly miasma pervades the atmosphere and 
 in summer renders it totally unfit to be inhaled by human lungs de- 
 positing the seeds of debility and disease with every inspiration In 
 these rooms all the processes of cooking, eating, sleeping, washing, 
 working, and living are indiscriminately performed. 2 
 
 Bad as these conditions were, they were not the worst. 
 The wages of Irish laborers in Brooklyn were so low that 
 they could not afford to pay any rent at all, so "they were 
 allowed to build miserable shanties on ground allotted them 
 by the contractors on the plot occupied by them in perform- 
 ing the work.'* 3 
 
 In the '6o's there was a "shanty population "of about 
 20,000 on the upper west side of Manhattan Island. It 
 was composed of Germans and Irish. They were largely 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. 45 2 ~453- 
 
 a Helen L. Sumner: Report of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in 
 
 the United States, vol. ix., p. 135. 
 
 3 Documentary History of American Industrial Society, vol. viii., pp. 225- 
 
 226; quoting from New York Weekly Tribune, May 2, 1846, p. 3, col. 3. 
 
232 Immigration and Labor 
 
 day laborers, employed by contractors in grading, paving, 
 and sewering the streets, and in the removal of rock, or in 
 excavating for public purposes. In a typical shanty, 
 according to an inspector of the council of hygiene, "domi- 
 ciliary and personal cleanliness is almost impossible. In 
 one room are found the family, chairs, usually dirty and 
 broken, cooking utensils, stove, often a bed, a dog or cat, 
 and sometimes more or less poultry. On the outside, by 
 the door in many cases, are pigs and goats and additional 
 poultry. There is no sink or drainage, and the slops are 
 thrown upon the ground." 1 
 
 Gloomy pictures of the housing conditions which pre- 
 vailed in the '6o's are drawn in contemporary reports of 
 medical inspectors. They speak in general terms of "the 
 contracted alleys; the underground, murky, and pestilential 
 cellars ; the tenement house, with its hundreds of occupants 
 where each cooks, eats, and sleeps in a single room without 
 light or ventilation, surrounded with filth, in an atmosphere 
 foul, fetid, and deadly." 3 
 
 The Thirteenth Ward was densely crowded with working classes, 
 the majority of whom were Irish; Germans ranked next, and Am- 
 ericans last. . . . The ward showed a high rate of sickness and 
 mortality, owing to the over-crowded and ill-ventilated dwellings and 
 to the ignorant and careless habits of the people themselves. . . . 
 From Fortieth to Fiftieth Street the foreign population was mainly 
 Irish or of Irish descent, packed in filthy tenements and of the most 
 unclean and degraded personal habits. . . . The tenement houses in 
 which most of the foreign population found their homes were certainly 
 little calculated to develop high social and moral types, and indeed 
 brought to bear influences working directly the other way. 3 
 
 The following description of the tenements in Sheriff 
 Street, which was then settled by Germans, is quoted from 
 contemporary sources: 
 
 The attic rooms are used to deposit the filthy rags and bones as they 
 are taken from the gutters and slaughterhouses. The yards are filled 
 with dirty rags hung up to dry, sending forth their stench to all the 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 457. 
 
 Ibid., p. 454. a Ibid., p. 458. 
 
The Standard of Living 233 
 
 neighborhood. . . . The tenants are all Germans. . . . They are 
 exceedingly filthy in person and their bedclothes are as dirty as the floors 
 they walk on. Their food is of the poorest quality, and their feet and 
 hands, doubtless their whole bodies are suffering from what they call 
 rheumatism, but which in reality is a prostrate nervous system, the 
 result of foul air and inadequate supply of nutritious food. . . . The 
 yards are all small and the sinks running over with filth. . . . Not one 
 decent sleeping apartment can be found on the entire premises and not 
 one stove properly arranged. The carbonic-acid gas, in conjunction 
 with the other emanations from bones, rags, and human filth, defies 
 description. The rooms are 6 by 10 feet; bedrooms 5 by 6 feet. The 
 inhabitants lead a miserable existence, and their children wilt and die 
 in their infancy. 1 
 
 When at length the tenement dwellers crowded the old 
 one-family residences to the utmost limit of their capacity, 
 the further growth of population led to the utilization 
 of the back yards, for building purposes. A special type 
 of rear tenement came into existence. The terrible con- 
 ditions that arose from lack of ventilation and sanitary 
 conveniences are vividly depicted in a report of a city 
 inspector concerning a square of front and rear tenements 
 which were occupied mostly by Irish: 
 
 In a majority of rear tenements . . . the apartments are dirty, dark, 
 and often reeking with filth, the walls wholly innocent of whitewash, and 
 the atmosphere impregnated with the disagreeable odor so peculiar to 
 tenant houses. In some the sun never shines, and the apartments are 
 so dark that unless seated near the window it is impossible to read 
 ordinary type; and yet the inspector often hears the hackneyed expres- 
 sion, "We have no sickness, thank God, " uttered by those whose sunken 
 eyes, pale cheeks, and colorless lips speak more eloquently than words of 
 the anaemic condition inevitably resulting from the absence of pure, fresh 
 air, and the general light of the sun. . . . The tenants seem to wholly 
 disregard personal cleanliness, if not the very first principles of decency, 
 their general appearance and actions corresponding with their wretched 
 abodes. This indifference to personal and domiciliary cleanliness is 
 doubtless acquired from a long familiarity with the loathsome surround- 
 ings, wholly at variance with all moral or social improvements, as well 
 as the first principles of hygienic science.* 
 
 The fundamental cause of congestion with all its attend- 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 461. *Ibid., p. 456. 
 
234 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ant evils is the fact that wage- workers must live within an 
 accessible distance from their places of work. This neces- 
 sity puts the owners of real estate in the factory district 
 in a position of advantage over the tenants. 
 
 The landlord took the utmost advantage of the situation by charging 
 the highest possible prices for the poorest possible accommodations, 
 and disregarding every law of health and decency in erecting big bar- 
 racks meant for occupation by the poor. 
 
 An inspector for the council of hygiene in 1864 
 thus reports the landlords' methods with regard to repairs: 
 
 Every expenditure of money which the law does not enforce to make 
 is refused; and blinds half swung and ready to fall and crash with the 
 first strong wind; doors long off their hinges, which open and shut by 
 being taken up bodily and put out of or in the way; chimneys as apt to 
 conduct the smoke into the room as out of it; stagnant, seething, over- 
 flowing privies, left uncleansed through the hot months of summer, 
 though pestilence itself should breed from them; hydrants out of repair 
 and flooding sink and entry; stairs which shake and quiver with every 
 step as you ascend them; and all this day after day, month after month, 
 year in and year out. 1 
 
 Such were the housing conditions to which the "old 
 immigrants" of Teuton and Celtic stock submitted for 
 more than a quarter of a century, at a time when the 
 population of New York was but a fraction of its present 
 size, and there was still an abundance of unimproved land 
 in the upper part of Manhattan Island. These conditions 
 are a thing of the past. The typical tenement house in the 
 Jewish and Italian sections of New York to-day is a decided 
 improvement upon the dwellings of the Irish and the Ger- 
 mans in the same sections a generation or two ago. "The 
 visitor of 1900 could go about dry-shod, at least, in tene- 
 ment yards and courts where thirty-five years before the 
 accumulation of what should have gone off in sewers and 
 drains made access almost impossible." 2 
 
 The causes of the present congestion in New York City 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 459. 
 a Ibid., p. 488. 
 
The Standard of Living 235 
 
 have been the subject of an exhaustive investigation by 
 Professor Pratt, of the New York School of Philanthropy. 
 Although believing that restriction of immigration would 
 have "salutary results in different directions," he found 
 from the mass of statistical evidence collected by him, that 
 congestion is produced by industrial factors which are not 
 related to immigration and over which the immigrants 
 have no control. We must abstain, for want of space, 
 from quoting his statistics. His conclusions are reproduced 
 in condensed form, yet, as nearly as possible verbatim, in 
 the following abstract 1 : 
 
 " New York City is the great mart of, the American conti- 
 nent. Every company or corporation of any size or import- 
 ance has offices, usually its principal offices, in New York 
 City. The New York market, therefore, is an exceedingly 
 important factor in the concentration of manufacturers 
 in that city. The fact that New York City is large and 
 commercially great, makes it a desirable place in which 
 to locate a manufacturing enterprise. A very large and 
 increasing importance should be attached to this element 
 as a factor in the congestion of manufactures in New York 
 City. During the last half century New York has been 
 changing from a purely commercial city to a manufacturing 
 center as well. The value of manufactured products has 
 increased nearly tenfold. The great bulk of the manufac- 
 turing in greater New York is carried on in Manhattan 
 below Fourteenth Street, on that small but immensely 
 valuable one-hundredth of the city's total land area. Of 
 the whole number of workers engaged in manufactures in 
 Manhattan, 321,488, or 66.8 per cent, work in factories 
 below Fourteenth Street, while only 160,368 or 33.2 per 
 cent work in the much larger area above Fourteenth Street. 
 The problem of congestion of population, then, seems to be 
 closely linked with that of congestion of industries. 
 
 "Population must live within an accessible distance of its 
 place of work. Hence, it is scarcely necessary to point 
 out how important a cause of congestion of population the 
 concentration of industry, trade, and commerce becomes. 
 
 1 Edward Ewing Pratt: Industrial Causes of Congestion of Population 
 in New York City, pp. 14, 15, 17, 20, 21, 39, 42, 94, 97, 138, 145, 146, 155, 
 166, 167, 182, 183, 185, 186, 187, 188, 204. 
 
236 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The conditions of labor exercise a preponderating influence 
 upon the lives of the workers. Long hours and low pay 
 have compelling force and necessitate the residence of the 
 overworked and underpaid in the over-crowded and con- 
 gested districts of New York City. Even the efficient work- 
 man counts the carfare to distant points a drain on his 
 income, and locates near the industrial districts. The 
 conclusion indicated is irresistible, that the factory and the 
 workshop are the predominant factor in the lives of these 
 workers, and that the factories in the crowded sections of 
 Manhattan are largely responsible for the problem of 
 congestion of population which confronts the city in these 
 districts. The latter being limited in size, buildings must 
 be erected which will house many families. Some students 
 of the problem have discovered the fact that in the most 
 congested districts there are to be found the largest pro- 
 portions of aliens. The conclusion is then drawn that 
 congestion is due to immigration. The best that can be 
 said of this generalization is that it is indeed a hasty one. 
 The tendency for people to group themselves together in a 
 strange land is most natural. The newly arrived immigrant 
 seeks his friends or relatives, if he has none, he seeks com- 
 panionship where he can understand and where he can be 
 understood. From this little nationality group, he makes 
 his start in the struggle of the New World. These steady 
 accessions of newly arrived immigrants no doubt augment 
 the crowded districts, but they are scarcely an important 
 cause. Similar tendencies of congregation among immi- 
 grants are found in sparsely settled Minnesota and in the 
 Dakotas, but we do not find congestion. The logical 
 explanation is, that there are other and perhaps more 
 fundamental causes at work. 
 
 "One of the most powerful lodestones of the city is the city 
 itself, and within the city, the center is the magnet. These 
 advantages of the city and the center of the city are not 
 purely pleasurable, but are social in the best sense of the 
 word. It is at the center of a great city like New York 
 that educational and cultural facilities are found most 
 highly developed. As a shrewd employer of men once said, 
 'A man can get more for nothing in New York City than 
 he can buy with his whole wage in a small town. ' He can 
 get more pleasure, more excitement, more education, than 
 he can anywhere else. The city contributes to every side 
 of a man, no matter how varied his nature. This is true, 
 
The Standard of Living 237 
 
 in general, of the city; it is pre-eminently true of the center 
 of the city's population, where congestion has occurred, or 
 is likely to occur. 
 
 "Congestion is often attributed to the inordinate desire 
 of certain races or nationalities to congregate. The Jews 
 and the Italians have each been accused of causing conges- 
 tion. These recent arrivals have no doubt largely inhabited 
 congested districts, but it seems unjust and unscientific 
 to assert that congestion is caused by these groups of people. 
 In fact the entire reasoning underlying this theory of 
 congestion is based on a priori logic and is open to serious 
 objections. The returns of workers employed in Lower 
 Manhattan, in the uptown factories, in Brooklyn, near 
 Brooklyn Bridge, in Williamsburg, in Queens Borough, near 
 the 34th Street Ferry, and in suburban factories located on 
 the outskirts of Greater New York, display certain uni- 
 form tendencies which may be formulated as follows: 
 
 "A working population tends to live in the immediate 
 vicinity of its place of employment. 
 
 "The distribution of a working population is greatly 
 influenced by such industrial factors as hours of work and 
 wages. The degree of distribution may be termed residence- 
 mobility. 
 
 "The residence-mobility of a working population varies 
 inversely with the length of the working day or week. 
 The longer the working day the intenser the congestion. 
 
 "The residence-mobility of a working population varies 
 directly with the wages or labor. The workers earning the 
 lowest wages are the most congested. 
 
 "The nationality or race of the workers has no appre- 
 ciable effect upon the residence-mobility of a working 
 population. 
 
 " In the most congested districts a large proportion of the 
 workers find it impossible to secure adequate or comfortable 
 living quarters. Hence we find that the workers employed 
 in Lower Manhattan take, on the average, a longer time in 
 getting to and from work than the workers in any other 
 group. Nor do the workers employed near Manhattan 
 show any tendency whatever, that could be interpreted as 
 indicating a preference for the congested districts. The 
 workers prefer to live near their places of employment. 
 This is the tendency despite nationality, which may be 
 urging them to live among their countrymen. These 
 facts indicate that the recently-arrived Italian or Russian 
 
238 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Jew does not prefer to live in the congested districts. 
 They are found to reside near their places of work, and 
 when the two alternatives are open to them, the larger 
 proportion embraces the opportunity to live among decent 
 surroundings. The most important finding in the investi- 
 gation of the group of workers employed in Brooklyn near 
 the Brooklyn Bridge is the relatively small proportion who 
 live in Manhattan, in spite of its accessibility. With the 
 crowded down-town colony of Little Italy easily accessible, 
 only 37.8 per cent of these Italians live in Lower Manhattan. 
 Of the group working in Brooklyn, there are more than 
 fifty per cent less Italians, and almost fifty per cent less 
 Russians and Jews living in Manhattan, than of the groups 
 that are employed in Manhattan. This fact shows the 
 effect of concentrating industries in Manhattan and demon- 
 strates what a difference exists when the factories are 
 located only just outside. Manufacturers in suburban 
 sites within accessible distance of Manhattan remove their 
 workmen from the congested districts. The workmen, 
 when given the chance, prefer to live in the less crowded 
 sections. This is true even of the much-maligned Italian 
 and Jew. 
 
 "When the influence of immigration and the distribution 
 of the various nationalities are carefully considered, the 
 tendency of our immigrant people to live in congested 
 districts near the work places cannot occasion very great 
 surprise, in view of the fact that our foreign population is 
 the most unskilled, and therefore, the lowest paid, and that 
 it is employed in industries working the longest hours. 
 This tendency and the fact that aliens form the largest 
 part of our most congested population is admitted has 
 been frequently seized upon as the explanation of conges- 
 tion, and hence these theorists ihave demanded restriction 
 of immigration as a remedy for congestion. However, if 
 congestion were due to the desire or willingness of our alien 
 population to live in congested districts, we should expect 
 those employed within a reasonable distance of Manhattan 
 to make every effort to live there. But this is exactly 
 contrary to the facts as brought out in the preceding study. 
 The Italians, Jews, and Slavic peoples, who have oftenest 
 been indicted for congestion, have proved themselves 
 innocent and their positive unwillingness to live in Man- 
 hattan, when escape is offered, is evidenced by every group 
 of workers in the factories outside of Lower Manhattan. 
 
The Standard of Living 239 
 
 If, therefore, this mass of evidence has any weight, the 
 oftrepeated theory of congestion that it is the result of 
 the preference of the people, the gregarious instinct is 
 disproved. 
 
 "The basic cause of congestion in all great cities is to be 
 found in the failure on the part of the community to provide 
 necessary safeguards. The first of these negative causes is 
 the lack of proper planning of the city. Had our cities 
 been laid out on broad, comprehensive plans, had our 
 streets been laid out on wide, intelligent lines, and adequate 
 parks provided, had our industrial and commercial districts 
 been segregated, and our residence districts reserved, some 
 of the very tap-roots of congestion would have been re- 
 moved. 
 
 "The lack of adequate building laws is closely linked to 
 that of city planning. The limitation of the area of the 
 lot which can be built upon, the height of the house, the 
 size of the rooms, are all factors which would definitely and 
 certainly confine and limit congestion. But even those 
 laws we have, have not been adequately enforced. Had our 
 laws been enforced in the best possible manner, we would 
 have gained a little in preventing congestion. Of the 
 local conditions peculiar to New York, which with thought 
 and foresight might have been prevented, the first and 
 foremost is the lack of adequate rapid transit. Whenever 
 it has been advantageous to do business in Lower Man- 
 hattan, it has been convenient, because of lack of transit 
 facilities, both to have a permanent place of business there 
 and to live there. Transit not only converged on Lower 
 Manhattan, but what there was of it simply conveyed 
 people into the crowded districts and 'dumped' them. 
 Had transit facilities to neighboring localities been con- 
 venient and adequate, the population might have availed 
 itself of the advantages of the central city, and business 
 might have flourished in other than down-town Man- 
 hattan districts. Important factors in the campaign for 
 the relief of congestion of population in Manhattan are: 
 first, the removal of factories from Manhattan, and their 
 distribution according to some comprehensive plan through- 
 out the outlying suburbs; second, the enactment of laws 
 to prevent the reproduction of bad living and housing con- 
 ditions in the other neighborhoods. This is city planning. ' ' 
 
 It is evident from Professor Pratt's analysis that conges- 
 
240 Immigration and Labor 
 
 tion in New York City is not wrought by the habits or 
 standards of living of the immigrants from Eastern and 
 Southern Europe, but is forced upon them by conditions 
 not of their own making. 
 
 As regards the effects of this congestion upon the rate of 
 wages, on the other hand, the determining factor is not the 
 discomfort suffered by the immigrant, but the amount he 
 must expend for rent. And it is a well-known fact that 
 house rent in New York is higher than in the rest of the 
 United States. The average rent in New York City for a 
 normal workingman's family, according to latest pre-war 
 statistics, was $13.50 to $14.00 a month, whereas in the 
 rest of the United States, it ranged from $8.25 to $11.00 
 per month. 1 The Jewish ,or Italian immigrant in New 
 York City was compelled to expend for rent about $1.00 a 
 week more than the wage-earners in small towns where the 
 native American workmen predominate. The American 
 workman may be better housed, yet when the manufacturer 
 employing immigrant labor in New York must meet in the 
 nation's market his competitor employing native American 
 labor in a small country town, it is the native American 
 workman, rather than the immigrant recently arrived in 
 New York from Southern or Eastern Europe, that can be 
 induced or coerced to accept a lower wage. 
 
 C. Housing Conditions in the Country at Large 
 
 In a retrospective view of the New England textile 
 manufacturing towns of the period when the operatives in 
 
 Amos G. Warner; American Charities, p. 180. "Not only is the 
 cost of housing less in cities outside of New York, but the accommodations 
 enjoyed are better. Detached houses are the rule, with no question 
 of access to light and air. The number of rooms is 3, in only I case of 
 the 53 (Rochester) ; only 6 report 4 rooms, and 7 and 8 rooms are of fre- 
 quent occurrence. . . . For $8.00 a month in the smaller towns of the 
 State, and $10.00 or $n.oo in the cities like Syracuse, better accommo- 
 ations can be secured than for $15.00 in Manhattan." Chapin: 
 The Standard of Living in New York City, p. 303. 
 
The Standard of Living 241 
 
 the mills were recruited among the farm girls of the neigh- 
 borhood, the Immigration Commission has discovered a 
 description of their living conditions "which affords a 
 pleasing contrast with the Lowell of the present." "The 
 life in the boarding houses was very agreeable. These 
 houses belonged to the corporation," 1 i. e. t they were 
 "company houses," in modern parlance. Dr. Sumner, 
 however, in her History of Women in Industry in the 
 United States, written for the U. S. Bureau of Labor, quotes 
 other contemporary testimony less bucolic in character. 
 From the same town of Lowell, complaints were made in 1845 
 that a dozen or more of the "daughters of New England" 
 were crowded into "the same hot, ill-ventilated attic." 
 The boarding houses of the Tremont mills in 1847 were 
 described in the following extract from a letter: 
 
 T is quite common for us to write on the cover of a bandbox, and 
 sit upon a trunk, as tables or chairs in our sleeping rooms are all out 
 of the question, because there is no room for such articles, as 4 to 6 
 occupy every room, and of course trunks and bandboxes constitute 
 furniture for the rooms we occupy. A thing called a light-stand, a 
 little more than a foot square, is our table for the use of 6. Wash- 
 stands are uncommon articles it has never been my lot to enjoy their 
 use, except at my own expense. 3 
 
 Comparative statistics of house tenancy in Boston in 
 1855 and 1900 show that in the middle of the nineteenth 
 century the tenement house population was as numerous, 
 in proportion, as in our day. This can be seen from Table 
 71 on page 242. 
 
 Overcrowded and filthy tenement houses were as preva- 
 lent forty years ago in Boston, as in New York. There 
 also the conversion of the single family house into a tene- 
 ment house, where a whole family was jammed in every 
 room, was productive "of filth and grime." An early 
 report of the Massachusetts Labor Bureau, describing the 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 508-509. 
 * Helen L. Sumner: Report of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in 
 the United States, vol. ix., pp. 87-88. 
 
242 . Iitomigration and Labor 
 
 $* 
 
 tenement houses of Boston and their surroundings, speaks 
 of "hovels rotting with damp and mould," of "puddles 
 reeking with stenchy garbage,*' of "putrid cesspools and 
 uncleansed drains, befouled with unspeakable nastiness." 1 
 
 TABLE 71. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF THE FAMILIES OF BOSTON ACCORDING TO 
 NUMBER OF FAMILIES PER HOUSE, 1855 AND IQOO. 3 
 
 Per cent of families 
 Living in 1855 1900 
 
 1 family houses 31.8 32.2 
 
 2 family houses 23.5 26.5 
 
 Tenements with 3 or more families 44.7 41 .3 
 
 Total 100.0 100.0 
 
 The degree of congestion at the close of the '6o's is exem- 
 plified by the description of a block of tenements consisting 
 of fifty-six rooms which were occupied by fifty-four families, 
 mostly Irish. There were also a few English and colored 
 families among them. The stairways were rotten and 
 dangerous. The ventilation of the rooms was very poor. 
 Washing, ironing, and drying were all done in the only room 
 which was both a living room and a sleeping room. 3 
 
 The two-room tenements on Meander Street consisted 
 of a living and a sleeping room, both dark and damp and 
 dirty. Other tenements visited were old, rickety frame 
 houses with plastering broken down and full of holes through 
 which rain and sun freely entered. In the summer the 
 houses swarmed with vermin. These houses were occupied 
 by American and Irish tenants. 
 
 Another tenement house in Kingston Court was a wooden 
 building consisting of six apartments, some with three 
 rooms and some with only one to each. The living rooms 
 
 1 Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor, jd Annual Report 
 (1871-1872), pp. 437-438. 
 
 3 Census of Boston, 1855, p. n (percentages computed); XII. Census 
 of United States. Population, Part II., p. 186, Table XCVIII. 
 
 3 Reports of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1870, pp. 
 164-180. 
 
The Standard of Living 243 
 
 were 10 by 14; the sleeping rooms 7 by 9. The sun never 
 penetrated the sleeping rooms. Water was obtained from 
 a hydrant in the yard upon which twenty-six families 
 depended. Broken windows patched up with boards and 
 rags, rickety and broken-down stairs were not unusual. 
 We quote the concluding sentence of the report : 
 
 We could describe other tenement-house abominations of the same 
 foulness and beastly defilement, but it would be but a repetition of 
 nastiness and negligence, and for which neither memory or dictionary 
 could supply words not yet used, or language adequate to the filthy 
 picturing. 1 
 
 In the smaller Massachusetts towns, the working people 
 were as badly housed as in Boston. The following is 
 reproduced from contemporary testimony given by a 
 canvasser who went through many of the tenements of 
 Danvers : 
 
 Take them as a whole, they are horrid; those belonging to the factory 
 especially. There are tenement houses there that ought not to be 
 occupied. Four families have complained to me, that if they go to 
 bed at night and there comes a shower, they have to rise up and put 
 dishes in different places to catch the water, and that they can't sleep 
 in their beds; and to prove it I went and examined and saw it was 
 actually worse than they had said; one house, especially, where a person 
 came to me, and I saw he did n't look right, and I said, "Are you going 
 to work?" "No," he says, "had no sleep last night." It had been 
 raining and his mother had been baking and preparing things for the 
 house, and, in the morning almost everything had swum off and gone 
 away in all directions. . . . Another house, I was almost afraid to 
 go into. I could see right through into the cellar; the plastering was 
 entirely off the ceiling and they told me it leaked in just about the same 
 way. There is another house, where there is a yard square without a 
 shingle on it; and then another has an addition to it, and you can put 
 your whole arm right in betwixt the two. It is more like a pig-pen 
 than a decent house . . . when people are in the water-closet, the 
 people on the road can see them. There is not a good tenement in the 
 village. 2 
 
 1 Reports of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1871, pp. 
 517-531. 
 
 * Ibid., pp. 442-443- 
 
244 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The same conditions were reported from Salem. The 
 houses were seldom repaired, the plumbing was very poor, 
 and the pump water was often made unfit for drinking 
 purposes by the washings of the yard. The odor in the 
 houses was bad. The following description of a house at 
 No. 1 8 Lemon Street, is quoted as an extreme case, which 
 nevertheless indicates what conditions were tolerated in 
 those days: 
 
 In connection with the kitchen, and only separated by a door was the 
 pantry, quite reluctantly shown us by the mistress. She said that it 
 being very much out of repair, and not fit to be used as such, they con- 
 cluded it was best to turn it into a cowshed. Here were two cows, and 
 all the accompaniments usually found in a stable, in direct connection 
 with the kitchen, filling the house with its unmitigated stench. In this 
 place pigs and hens were once kept, besides the cow, the former on all 
 occasions making the freest use of the domestic apartments. 1 
 
 About the same time (1872) shanty dwellers were found 
 among the laborers of Massachusetts. The paymaster of 
 tunnel laborers employed at North Adams in 1872 testified 
 that many of them lived in shanties on the works and even 
 kept boarders. ''The miners, rockmen, etc., who have no 
 families, board at the shanties. They are filthy, dirty 
 places. 
 
 The congestion and squalor of the past were no better 
 than the worst housing conditions that were found by the 
 investigators of the Immigration Commission among the 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe. Yet 
 the tenement-house dwellers of forty years ago were all of 
 Teuton and Celtic stock. As stated in a previous chapter, 
 contemporary observers sought to explain the bad housing 
 conditions of the Irish immigrants by the low standard of 
 living of the people of Ireland. 3 Although living conditions 
 
 1 Reports of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1870, pp. 372 
 and 380. 
 
 a Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor. Third Annual Report 
 (1871-1872), pp. 440-441- 
 
 * Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 459. 
 
The Standard of Living 245 
 
 in Ireland have greatly improved since those days, yet they 
 still remain far below the average of the most overcrowded 
 sections of the great American cities. 
 
 The investigation of the Immigration Commission was 
 confined to "the overcrowded, poor quarters of the city"; 
 in the households investigated, the average number of 
 persons per room was I.34. 1 In the city of Dublin, accord- 
 ing to the census of 1901, four fifths of all tenements con- 
 sisted of four rooms or less with an average of 2.20 persons 
 per room. More than one third of all tenements had three 
 persons .or more per room. Three fifths of all tenements 
 consisted of one or two rooms only. 2 In the whole of 
 Ireland, one third of all families lived in two rooms or less. 3 
 There were 38,086 families of three or more persons living 
 in one room each. These extremes of congestion comprised 
 4.2 per cent of all Irish families. The details are given in 
 
 Table 72. 
 
 TABLE 72. 
 
 NUMBER OF TENEMENTS OF ONE ROOM OCCUPIED BY THREE OR MORB 
 PERSONS, I90I.4 
 
 Number of 
 Occupied by 
 
 3 persons 
 
 4 persons 
 
 5 persons 
 
 6 persons 
 
 7 persons 
 
 8 persons 
 
 9 persons 
 
 10 persons 
 
 1 1 persons 
 
 12 persons or more 
 
 Total 38,036 
 
 If it is maintained that the immigrant tends to transplant 
 to the American soil the standard of living of his native 
 country, it must follow from the latest statistics of housing 
 conditions in Ireland that even the present-day Irish immi- 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. tit., pp. 117, 119. 
 3 See Appendix, Table XVI. 
 
 ' Census of Ireland, 1901. General Report, p. 112, Table 9; p. 173, 
 Table 49. Ibid., Table 10. 
 
246 Immigration and Labor 
 
 grants are open to the same objection as the immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. The fact that the investi- 
 gation of the Immigration Commission discovered among 
 the Irish no overcrowding approaching that of their mother 
 country must be taken to mean one of two things : either its 
 investigators overlooked the recent Irish immigrants and 
 selected only old Irish settlers who had in the course of time 
 advanced on the social scale, or else the standard of living 
 of the recent Irish immigrants in the United States was not 
 determined by their living conditions in Ireland, but 
 depended upon their earning ability in this country. In 
 either case the race theory of economics fathered by the 
 Commission fails. 
 
 That bad housing conditions are not the exclusive char- 
 acteristic of the immigrant, but are found under like econ- 
 omic conditions among the native wage-earners as well, has 
 been shown by the investigation of the Immigration Commis- 
 sion in Alabama, where there are practically no foreigners 
 whose competition might be supposed to have forced down 
 the American standard of living. In the outlying towns, 
 beyond the territory immediately adjacent to Birmingham, 
 many of the bituminous coal mines are operated exclusively 
 by native labor and native white Americans are employed 
 as unskilled laborers. "In these environments the home 
 of the native white laborer is frequently devoid of the more 
 modern equipment and sanitation." 1 Mr. Streightoff , in 
 his study of the standard of living, uses stronger language. 
 According to him, "in the Southern mill towns conditions 
 are about at their worst." The number of foreign-born 
 wage-earners in the Southern mills is negligible and cannot 
 affect the housing situation. The mill workers are country 
 people of old American stock. And yet the company 
 houses in which they live "are neither sheathed, plastered, 
 nor papered, and the tenants suffer intensely from the 
 occasional cold weather." 3 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 229. 
 3 Streightoff: The Standard of Living, pp. 76-77 and 92. 
 
 
The Standard of Living 247 
 
 The preceding comparison between the present and the 
 past, on the one hand, and between native and foreign- 
 born mill and mine workers, on the other, irresistibly leads 
 to the conclusion that the cause of bad housing conditions 
 is not racial, but economic. That the difference among 
 wage-earners in this respect "depends, of course . . . 
 upon the income, " is admitted, "to a considerable extent, " 
 by the experts of the Immigration Commission with the 
 qualification, however, that the difference depends "appar- 
 ently also upon the insistence" of the tenants themselves 
 upon having proper accommodations. * If the South Italian 
 or Irish laborers, or the Southern white mill hands, are not 
 so well housed as their Welsh foreman, or English engineer, 
 it is because, apart from their inability to raise the rent of a 
 substantial dwelling, they do not "insist" upon having it 
 for the money they are able to pay. That the English or 
 German laborers and factory hands of past generations 
 lived in filthy tenements, must have been due, by the same 
 method of reasoning, to lack of "insistence" on their part 
 upon better accommodations. This view implies a belief 
 that the law of supply and demand will assure to the 
 wage- workers such homes as they will "insist" upon. The 
 economic distinction between land and other forms of 
 property is lost sight of. 
 
 The inadequacy of the law of supply and demand in the 
 matter of housing was conclusively demonstrated by all 
 investigations of the New York housing system, which 
 "agreed in showing the landlord, rather than the helpless 
 tenant, as the primitive cause of tenement evils." 2 
 
 In the mill towns and mining camps of to-day, as in the 
 
 1 "There seems to be a decided difference . . . among the various 
 races the South Italians and the Syrians among the recent immigrants, 
 the Irish among the older immigrants, not being so well provided with 
 sanitary equipment as are the other races. This depends, of course, to 
 a considerable extent, upon the income, but apparently also upon the 
 insistence of the persons themselves upon having proper water supply 
 and toilet accommodations." Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 126. 
 
 3 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 459. 
 
248 Immigration and Labor 
 
 mill towns of Massachusetts in the days of the "old 
 immigration," the helplessness of the tenant is aggravated 
 by the combination of the landlord and mill owner in the 
 same individual or corporation, whose income is derived 
 from house rents, as well as from manufacturing or mining. 
 "In many industrial localities," say Professors Jenks and 
 Lauck, "especially in those connected with the mining 
 industry, the so-called 'company-house* system prevails 
 under which the industrial worker . . . must live in a 
 house owned by the operating company and rented to him." x 
 This system is as common in the Anglo-Saxon towns of the 
 South, as in the Slav settlements of Pennsylvania. 3 If the 
 mill or mine worker were to "insist" upon a better 
 dwelling, he could not hold his position. 
 
 The Immigration Commission made no systematic 
 inquiries to ascertain the landlords' share of responsibility 
 for the overcrowding and unsanitary conditions of the 
 houses occupied by the new immigrants in industrial 
 communities. The outspoken tendency of its investiga- 
 tion was to lay the whole blame upon the habits of the 
 immigrants. There are scattered in its reports, however, 
 occasional items of information which tell the other side 
 of the story. The following description of a "company 
 house" is illuminating: 
 
 The type of company house most frequently seen in the locality 
 adjacent to Birmingham is a one-story frame building containing from 
 two to four rooms, the four-room houses being frequently divided into 
 two apartments. . . . They are usually devoid of any modern con- 
 veniences, such as bath or flush toilet. 
 
 But these houses are "built in close proximity to the 
 steel, iron, or coke yard in which the laborers are em- 
 ployed," 3 and they have no other choice but to take such 
 houses as the company provides for them, or to travel a 
 distance to and from work. 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 279 
 
 * Streightoff, loc. cit., pp. 76-77. 
 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 232. 
 
The Standard of Living 249 
 
 From an account relating to another locality we learn 
 that the rent paid by the recent immigrants "is excessive, 
 and yields an unusually large rate of return to his landlord." * 
 It may be surmised from this illustration that the income 
 from company houses also very likely "pays more than the 
 ordinary return on the cost of the building." 
 
 The effect of the emphasis, however, laid by the Com- 
 mission upon the "tendency . . . characteristic of the 
 South Italian and Slav races" to "settle in that section of 
 the town where . . . the house rent is reduced to a mini- 
 mum" 2 is to divert public attention from the responsibility 
 of the mine and mill operators for the insanitary condition 
 of the tenements provided by them for their employees. 3 
 The police power of the State is ample to protect the health 
 of the community from the ill effects of insanitary housing 
 conditions. Considered on its own merits, as a problem 
 in public hygiene, the housing of the mine and mill opera- 
 tives, whether native or foreign-born, has therefore no 
 relevancy to the subject of immigration. 
 
 In reality, however, the housing problem is drawn into 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, pp. 93-94. 
 
 * Ibid., p. 229. 
 
 * The following is quoted from a "description of a typical mining and 
 coke village" in Pennsylvania: 
 
 "The typical company village is exceedingly insanitary. . . . The 
 water supply of the coal and coke town is very impure and a source of 
 disease. The companies usually 'clean up' the towns once a year; 
 sometimes twice, but often not at all. There is little to stimulate 
 cleanliness on the part of the tenants under such circumstances. The 
 mine operators say that the existing conditions result from the fact that the 
 foreigner is too dirty for the town to be other than what it is, but whether 
 this is true or not, it seems that very little effort is made to improve the 
 living conditions." (Ibid., vol. 6, p. 323.) 
 
 The defense is very typical, indeed. Because " the foreigner is dirty, " 
 the mining company which owns the village provides him with impure 
 water which is a source of disease, and cleans up the village only twice 
 a year. It is evident that the tenants cannot build water-works, nor 
 can they install a system of sewerage. It would not avail them to 
 "insist" upon these improvements, as there is no place to which they 
 could move in case of refusal, these conditions being "typical." 
 
250 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the discussion of immigration only collaterally, as an 
 argument in support of a theory. The Immigration Com- 
 mission has filled its volumes with statistical tables, some of 
 which show that the English-speaking wage-workers are 
 better housed than the immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe, and others that the earnings of the former 
 are higher. The impression conveyed by the race classifi- 
 cation 1 is that the wages of the immigrants from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe are low because they are willing to 
 live in crowded quarters, whereas the wages of the English- 
 speaking workmen are higher, because they "insist" upon 
 the American standard of living. The Immigration Com- 
 mission's own statistics, however, contain a refutation of 
 this theory. 
 
 In the first place, it appears that there is the widest 
 variation among wage-earners of each race with respect to 
 housing, which shows that there is no common standard 
 of living for all wage-earners of the same race, but that it 
 varies for the individuals of the same race. Neither do the 
 low rents paid by some of them force down the earnings of 
 others of the same race, as demonstrated by the wide varia- 
 tions in earnings among individuals of the same race. 
 
 In the second place, it is found that "the household of 
 immigrants, as compared with the native born wage-earners 
 pays, generally speaking, the same if not higher rent per 
 room." 2 In some districts the average monthly rent per 
 apartment is also higher for recent immigrants than for 
 American wage-earners of native parentage. In Ensley, 
 
 1 Some of the "race" distinctions are unique. Thus we are informed 
 that the Macedonians paid $5.53 per apartment, whereas the Greeks 
 paid $5.94 and the Bulgarians only $4.28. (Ibid., vol. 9, p. 234, Table 
 687.) It can be found in the Commission's own Dictionary of Races 
 that Macedonia is merely a political division with a mixed population 
 consisting chiefly of Bulgarians and Greeks. Professors Jenks and 
 Lauck also comment upon the per capita jnonthly rent payments of 
 the Bulgarians who paid only $0.97, and the Macedonians who paid 
 $0.78. (Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 131-132.) 
 
 3 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t p. 122. 
 
The Standard of Living 251 
 
 Ala., e. ., the latter paid on an average $5.40 per apartment, 
 the Greeks, $5.94, and the Poles, $5.98. The lowest average 
 rent per room was paid by the native white of native 
 parentage, viz., $1.38; the new immigrants ranged in the 
 following order: Slovaks, $1.73; Bulgarians, $1.82; Poles, 
 $1.91; South Italians, $2.09; Greeks, $2.93. 1 
 
 It is believed, however, that the difference in rent is 
 reduced by overcrowding, which is "most frequently shown 
 by the keeping of boarders or lodgers." 2 Great stress is 
 laid upon the fact that the Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 "break the independence of family life by taking boarders 
 or lodgers into the home," whereas "the native American 
 and older immigrant employees maintain an independent 
 form of family life," though they send their wives and 
 children to the factory. 3 It is worthy of note, as a his- 
 torical parallel, that in 1873 General Walker spoke of "the 
 detestable American vice of 'boarding* . . . uprooting the 
 ancient and honored institutions of the family." 4 The 
 Commission has laboriously figured out for each race the 
 percentage of families taking lodgers or boarders. Aside 
 from the merits of this criterion which will be considered 
 later, it is open to question, whether the figures of the 
 Commission may be accepted as typical. A similar inves- 
 tigation recently made by the United States Bureau of 
 Labor led to widely divergent results. Out of 1139 Ameri- 
 can households studied by the Immigration Commission 
 only 10 per cent had boarders or lodgers; out of 15,161 
 American households, however, studied by the Bureau 
 of Labor 22.23 P er cen t kept boarders or lodgers. The 
 variation of the percentage by race in the statistics of the 
 Immigration Commission was from o to 79.3 per cent, 
 whereas in the statistics of the United States Bureau of 
 Labor the range of variation was from 16.50 to 30.77 per 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9., p. 234, Table 687. 
 
 2 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 122. 
 
 a Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 158, 161. 
 
 * Walker: Discussions in Economics and Statistics, p. 43. 
 
252 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 cent. The discrepancies between the two series of figures 
 relating to the old immigration are shown in Table 73. 
 
 TABLE 73. 
 
 PER CENT OF FAMILIES KEEPING BOARDERS OR LODGERS AMONG THE 
 RACES OF THE OLD IMMIGRATION. 1 
 
 Nativity 
 
 Source of information 
 
 Immigration 
 Commission 
 
 United States 
 Bureau of Labor 
 
 
 .0 
 2.2 
 
 4.1 
 
 6-3 
 6.4 
 
 7-i 
 9.6 
 
 20.13 
 26.89 
 
 23.51 
 26.78 
 30.71 
 25.92 
 2379 
 
 Welsh 
 
 Scotch . , 
 
 
 Irish 
 
 English . . 
 
 
 
 That two official investigations separated by a brief 
 interval of six or seven years have brought such widely 
 divergent results, can probably be accounted for by the 
 fact that the investigations of the Immigration Commission 
 were concentrated upon selected industrial communities, 
 where the English-speaking immigrants were mostly high- 
 priced skilled mechanics, whereas the new immigrants were 
 nearly all unskilled laborers; it has been shown, however, 
 in Chapter VII. that each race is represented in every occu- 
 pation. The investigation of the United States Bureau of 
 Labor, on the other hand, was made in the leading indus- 
 trial centers of thirty-three States and is believed to be 
 "representative of the industrial portion of the country as 
 a whole. " a 
 
 Apart, however, from the doubtful value of the statistics 
 collected by the Immigration Commission on the subject 
 of boarders and lodgers, the fatal defect of its race per- 
 
 Jenks and Lauck, loc. tit., p. i6oT Eighteenth Annual Report 
 of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 261. 
 
 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 39. 
 
The Standard of Living 253 
 
 centages is that they assume by implication a communistic 
 system of housekeeping among the foreign-born. In 
 reality, however, the 52 per cent of the Croatians who keep 
 boarders or lodgers do not help to pay the rent of the other 
 48 per cent who keep none. The latter must themselves 
 pay the rent in full, which is at least as high as that paid by 
 the natives. It is evident that the wages of those who have 
 no lodgers must be sufficient to enable them to pay the 
 same rent as the native Americans, which goes to show that 
 those of them who do keep lodgers do not force down the 
 earnings of their countrymen. 
 
 That overcrowding is not a racial characteristic, but an 
 economic phenomenon, appears from the following table 
 showing the comparative frequency of the practice of 
 keeping boarders or lodgers in families of foreign-born 
 garment workers and woolen mill operatives classified by 
 
 annual earnings. 
 
 TABLE 74- 
 
 PER CENT OF FOREIGN-BORN FAMILIES IN WHICH WIFE HAS EMPLOY- 
 MENT OR KEEPS BOARDERS OR LODGERS, BY YEARLY EARNINGS 
 OF HUSBAND. x 
 
 Husband's earnings. 
 
 Per cent of wives keep 
 
 ng boarders or lodgers 
 
 
 Garment workers 
 
 Woolen mill operatives 
 
 Under $400 .... 
 
 28.2 
 
 61 4 
 
 $400 and under $600 
 
 10.6 
 
 AX ? 
 
 $600 and over 
 
 IO.O 
 
 7T 
 
 
 
 
 The nationalities comprised in the preceding table are 
 Scotch, Irish, Germans, Norwegians, French, Bohemians, 
 Hebrews, Lithuanians, Poles, South Italians, and Syrians. 
 As shown by the figures, the percentage of families with 
 boarders and lodgers 3 decreases with the increase of 
 earnings. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, Table 38, p. 685; 
 vol. ii, Table 45, p. 310. 
 
 1 The comparative value of the figures could not be affected by the 
 
254 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The same effect is produced by differences in rent. 
 Among iron and steel workers "both the native and foreign 
 households exhibit the smallest proportion having boarders 
 or lodgers in the South." The reason is that rents are 
 considerably lower in the South than in other sections of 
 the country. 1 Of the South Italian iron workers in the 
 Pittsburgh district 70.6 per cent keep boarders and lodgers, 
 whereas in the Birmingham district there are only 3 per 
 cent with boarders and lodgers. Among the Slovaks the 
 percentages are respectively 43.9 and 15.0.* 
 
 The United States Bureau of Labor has made a compari- 
 son of the expenditures for rent per person in 3908 foreign 
 and 7248 native "normal" families, which have no children 
 of working age, nor any boarders or lodgers. The results 
 for the North Atlantic and North Central States compare 
 
 as follows: 
 
 TABLE 75. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL RENT PER FAMILY AND PER INDIVIDUAL IN NORMAL 
 FAMILIES, BY NATIVITY, IN NORTHERN STATES. 3 
 
 Nativity 
 
 North Atlantic 
 
 North Central 
 
 Per family 
 
 \ 
 
 Per individual 
 
 Per family 
 
 Per individual 
 
 Native 
 
 $125.54 
 118.21 
 
 $33-25 
 29.09 
 
 $97.58 
 91.94 
 
 $2445 
 22.O2 
 
 
 Difference .... 
 
 $7-33 
 
 $ 4-16 
 
 $5.64 
 
 $ 2.43 
 
 small proportion of married women working for wages who were found 
 in only 5 per cent of all foreign-born households studied by the Immigra- 
 tion Commission. 
 
 1 Cottages very similar to, but not so good as those for which the 
 southern mill operatives pay a rent of $3.00 to $3.50 per month, rent 
 in Southwestern Illinois at from $14.00 to $16.00 per month. (Ibid., 
 vol. 9, p. 93.) 
 
 a Ibid., vol. 8, p. 105. 
 
 3 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table V., H. 
 and O., pp. 578, 589, 590. Other sections are omitted from this com- 
 
The Standard of Living 
 
 255 
 
 The difference in the amount of rent paid by native and 
 foreign-born wage-earners amounts to fourteen cents a 
 week per family or eight cents a week per person in the North 
 Atlantic States and to eleven cents a week per family or 
 five cents a week per person in the North Central States. 
 This is the extent to which the scrimping on rent enables 
 the average immigrant to underbid the native wage-earner 
 in the labor market. In Table 75 all foreign-born are 
 combined in one group. In Table 76 the foreign-born are 
 distinguished by nationality for the country as a whole. 
 
 TABLE 76. 
 
 ANNUAL RENT PER FAMILY AND PER~INDIVIDUAL IN NORMAL FAMILIES, 
 BY NATIVITY OF HEAD OF FAMILY.* 
 
 Nativity of head of family 
 
 Per family 
 
 Per individual 
 
 Native white: 
 Foreign-born ... 
 
 $112 
 III 
 
 $29 
 
 27 
 
 Old immigration: 
 Canada 
 
 IOQ 
 
 27 
 
 England . . 
 
 125 
 
 JI 
 
 
 117 
 
 28 
 
 
 IIP 
 
 ^O 
 
 
 IOQ 
 
 26 
 
 New immigration : 
 Austria-Hungary 
 
 QO 
 
 22 
 
 Russia 
 
 IOI 
 
 2*\ 
 
 Ttalv.. 
 
 Q7 
 
 2$ 
 
 Another fundamental fact which has been noted by all 
 students of the housing problem is that the wage-earner 
 must expend more for rent in proportion to his income 
 in a large city than in a small town. "Whereas the 
 average outlay for rent in the income group $400-^500 in 
 the city is $120 or $125, that in the country as a whole is 
 $86.54."* The significance of this difference lies in the fact 
 
 parison because the averages for natives in the South may be reduced 
 by the inclusion of negroes. 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table V., J. 
 and P., pp. 581 and 591 respectively. 
 
 3 Streightoff: The Standard of Living, p. 12. 
 
256 Immigration and Labor 
 
 that the recent immigrants are mostly concentrated in 
 great cities, where rent is high, while the native American 
 workmen predominate in small towns with low rents. So 
 when the article produced by immigrant labor in a large 
 city must compete in the market with the article produced 
 by native American labor in a small country town, it is not 
 the recent immigrant that is able to underbid the native 
 American workman, but on the contrary the latter is in a 
 position to accept a cheaper wage. 1 
 
 D. Food 
 
 The Immigration Commission has expressed the opinion 
 that "while it [the new immigration] may not have lowered 
 in a marked degree the American standard of living it has 
 introduced a lower standard which has become prevalent 
 in the unskilled industry at large." 2 This conclusion rests 
 solely on the meagre statistics which were collected by the 
 Commission on the subject of housing. The inconclusive- 
 ness of these statistics has been shown in the preceding 
 section. The food expenditure which absorbs about two 
 fifths of the workman's income, 3 was not included by the 
 Commission in the regular program of its statistical investi- 
 gation. Its reports contain but a few budgets picked up 
 here and there in a casual way. It notes, however, "that, 
 generally speaking, the expenditures for meat are consider- 
 ably higher in the case of the more recent immigrants than 
 in the case of the older immigrant races and the whites 
 native-born of native father." 4 By way of illustration 
 
 1 The Industrial Commission found that the average rent paid by a 
 family of a garment worker in the city was $8.95 per month for three 
 rooms, whereas the country garment workers who did not own their 
 houses paid on an average $4.59 for a whole house. (Report of the 
 Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 730.) The difference in rent amount- 
 ed to $4.37 per month, i. e., to $1.00 per week. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 39. 
 
 * Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 96. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 356. 
 
The Standard of Living 257 
 
 the following items are quoted from some of the published 
 budgets. 
 
 The Magyar is a great consumer of meat. A butcher 
 states that a group of eight Magyar men on an average 
 eat 4 pounds of beef, 5 pounds of pork, 3 pounds of 
 Polish sausage, and 4 pounds of veal, and often in addi- 
 tion, bacon and ham and other cured meats, each day. 
 (Thus on an average, each man eats 2 pounds of meat 
 each day.) 
 
 The Bulgarians. Among them bread is the staple article 
 of diet. Each man will consume a three-pound loaf of 
 bread per day. They also use a small quantity of meat 
 each day, usually about a pound per man. (The experts 
 of the Commission consider one pound a day per man "a 
 small quantity." Few boarding houses patronized by 
 university professors serve meat in greater quantities.) 
 
 The kind of food consumed daily by a Bulgarian couple 
 was about as follows 1 : 
 
 Breakfast: Tea, cream, cheese, bread. 
 
 Dinner: Bread, some kind of meat or stew. 
 
 Supper: Bread, meat stew, or eggs. 
 
 Presumably these budgets were published by the Immi- 
 gration Commission, because they were regarded as 
 representative. 
 
 How do these food standards compare with the standard 
 of the native American workingman? We may accept as 
 the official definition of the American food standard the 
 ration fixed by act of x Congress for enlisted men on the 
 warships of the American navy. A specimen bill of fare 
 prepared in accordance with the Navy ration prescribed 
 by Congress, is as follows 2 : 
 
 Breakfast : Baked beans, tomato catsup, bread, butter, 
 coffee. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission! vol. 9, pp. 82-96. 
 
 a Frank J. Sheridan: "Italian, Slavic, and Hungarian Unskilled Immi- 
 grant Laborers in the United States." Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor , 
 No. 72, p. 466. 
 
258 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Dinner: Roast beef, brown gravy, string beans, sweet 
 potatoes, cottage pudding, vanilla sauce, bread, coffee. 
 
 Supper : Cold boiled ham, canned peaches, bread, butter, 
 tea. 
 
 Judged by this official standard, the Hungarian and 
 Bulgarian workmen, with their daily fare of one or two 
 pounds of meat per man, do not appear to have "intro- 
 duced a lower standard." 
 
 Concerning the Italians, material for a comparison of 
 their food expenditure with that of native white Americans 
 is furnished in the Report of the Immigration Commission 
 on iron and steel manufacturing in the South. The Italians 
 whose budgets were reported were all unskilled, earning 
 from $7.50 to $12.50 per week, with the exception of 
 one foreman of unskilled laborers, who was earning $15.00 
 and had an 1 8-year-old boy who contributed $7.00 a week 
 to the family income. The Americans were all skilled 
 mechanics with a weekly income of from $18.00 to $25.00, 
 except one carpenter whose wages were $12.00 a week. In 
 Table 77 the food expenditures of these families have been 
 reduced to nutrition units per man per day according to 
 the scale adopted by the United States Department of 
 Agriculture. x 
 
 Although the budgets secured by the investigation of 
 
 TABLE 77. 
 
 AVERAGE EXPENDITURE PER MAN PER DAY OF SELECTED FAMILIES OF 
 
 SOUTH ITALIAN AND NATIVE WHITE WORKERS IN THE IRON 
 
 AND STEEL DISTRICT OF THE SOUTH. 3 
 
 South Italian Cents Native White Cents 
 
 No. 3 41 No. 13 62 
 
 No. 7 37 No. 10 36 
 
 No. 6 36 No. ii 36 
 
 No. 2 30 No. 9 32 
 
 No. 4 28 _ No. 12 29 
 
 1 For an explanation of the method used, see Robert Coit Chapin : 
 The Standard of Living among Workingmen's Families in New York 
 City, pp. 125-126. a For details see Appendix, Table XVII. 
 
The Standard of Living 259 
 
 the Immigration Commission included none for unskilled 
 American workmen and only one for an Italian employed 
 in a supervisory capacity, all the rest relating to unskilled 
 Italian laborers, yet the preceding table shows that the food 
 expenditure of the South Italian laborer is the same as 
 that of the Southern white skilled mechanic. 1 
 
 A special investigation of the expenditures of single 
 laborers in construction camps was made by the Bureau of 
 Labor in 1906. Fresh and salt meats were found to be 
 essential parts of the bills of fare of "Hungarian" and 
 "Slav" 2 laborers. The same information was obtained 
 concerning Hungarian laborers in an iron and steel plant 
 in Ohio: "They used beef as a rule three times a day." 
 At Hansford, Pa., the bill of fare of Hungarians and Slavs 
 on week days was as follows : 
 
 "Breakfast: Bread and coffee. Lunch: Four or five 
 sandwiches (beef). Dinner in the evening: Soup, boiled 
 or roast beef, one half to three fourths of a pound a head. 
 Vegetables and coffee." 
 
 According to Dr. Roberts, who has made a study of the 
 conditions of labor in the anthracite coal mines, "the Slavs 
 have good bread made of the best wheat or rye; they con- 
 sume daily about a pound of beef for boiling or of fat pork 
 or bologna sausage, a quantity of potatoes, cabbage, milk, 
 coffee, and beer, butter and cheese, sugar, eggs, and fish." 
 
 An earlier investigation made by the Bureau of Labor 
 among the Slav and Hungarian workmen in the iron mines 
 of Pennsylvania showed that, in 1890, their bill of fare 
 included "two pounds of meat per man per day, one for 
 dinner and one for supper." 3 
 
 1 The one exceptionally high average, 62 cents per man per day, was 
 obtained from a native machinist, who was employed in the railroad 
 shops at $23.00 per week and had only his wife and a small child de- 
 pendent upon him. 
 
 a The term "Hungarian" often comprises all immigrants from 
 Hungary, most of whom belong to various Slav races. Bulgarians are 
 also " Slavs." 
 
 ? Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 72, p. 475. 
 
260 Immigration and Labor 
 
 With respect to Italians, a distinction must be drawn 
 between families and single men, or married men whose 
 families have remained in Italy. It is learned from the 
 investigation of the Bureau of Labor, that men who are 
 employed in construction camps live principally on vege- 
 tables and reduce their expenditures to a minimum, in an 
 effort to save as much as possible of their wages. Italian 
 families, however, do not differ in the matter of food 
 expenditures from families of other nationalities with the 
 same income. Beside the budgets of the Immigration 
 Commission which have been analyzed above, this fact is 
 brought out in Professor Chapin's monograph on the 
 standard of living among New York workingmen, based 
 upon a canvass of 391 families in the summer of 1907. 
 
 The following table, giving the classification of food 
 expenditures by income and nationality, is compiled from 
 Professor Chapin's budget statistics, the nationalities being 
 arranged in the descending order of their average expendi- 
 ture per man per day: 
 
 TABLE 78. 
 
 AVERAGE FOOD EXPENDITURES PER MAN PER DAY, BY INCOME AND 
 NATIONALITY 1 
 
 Income group and nationality Expenditure 
 
 Cents 
 
 $600 to $699: 
 
 Italian. 31.1 
 
 Bohemian 25.5 
 
 Teutonic 25.3 
 
 Austrian, Hungarian, and other S. E. European 24.0 
 
 Native white 23.9 
 
 Colored 23.5 
 
 Russian 23.1 
 
 Irish 20.8 
 
 $700 to $799: 
 
 Italian 31.2 
 
 Irish 30.0 
 
 Teutonic 26.4 
 
 Native white 77 26.0 
 
 Colored 25.7 
 
 Austrian, Hungarian, and other S. E. European 25. 1 
 
 Bohemian 24.3 
 
 1 Robert Chapin, loc. cit., p. 141. 
 
The Standard of Living 261 
 
 Income group and nationality Expenditure 
 
 Cents 
 
 $800 to $899: 
 
 Italian 33.9 
 
 Native white 32.4 
 
 Bohemian 30.2 
 
 Teutonic 29.5 
 
 Irish 26.5 
 
 $900 to $999: 
 
 Native white 33.8 
 
 Teutonic 31.6 
 
 Italian 31.5 
 
 Irish 31.4 
 
 Austrian, Hungarian, and other Southeastern 
 
 European 31.1 
 
 Bohemian 28.5 
 
 $1000 to $1099: 
 
 Native white 38.1 
 
 Italian 34.3 
 
 Irish 32.0 
 
 Teutonic 31.9 
 
 The Italians in every income group expended more for 
 food than the Hungarians and Slavs. In every income 
 group below $900 per year, they expended more for food 
 than any other nationality, including native Americans. 1 
 Among the families with an income from $900 to $1000, the 
 Italians expended as much as the Teutons and the Irish, 
 and more than the Bohemians who are regarded as "desir- 
 able" immigrants. In the highest group the Italian ex- 
 pended more than the Celts and the Teutons. According 
 to Professor Underhill, of Yale University, who has made 
 a study of the nutritive value of various foods, 22 cents 
 per man per day must be regarded as the minimum upon 
 which physical existence can be maintained. 2 It appears 
 from the preceding table, that the Irish were the only race 
 which denied themselves that minimum when their earnings 
 were low. To sum up, Professor Chapin's analysis gives no 
 indication of a sliding scale of racial standards of living. 
 
 1 All the native Americans but one were sons of native fathers, or of 
 immigrants from Northern and Western Europe. The one exception 
 was the son of a Bohemian father, but Bohemians are not among the 
 "undesirable." Chapin, loc. cit., p. 39. 
 
 a Chapin. loc. cit., p. 126. 
 
262 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The most extensive investigation of its kind, comprising 
 more than 25,000 family budgets, was made by the United 
 States Bureau of Labor ten years ago. Table 79, compiled 
 from its report, is a comparative statement of food expendi- 
 tures of "normal" families classified by annual income and 
 country of birth. A "normal " family, it will be remembered, 
 is one supported solely by the earnings of husband and 
 father. All families with abnormally low incomes (under 
 $400 annually) have been excluded from this comparison. 
 No nationality with less than ten families in each income 
 group is shown separately, but all foreign-born are included 
 in the total. 
 
 TABLE 79. 
 
 EXPENDITURES FOR FOOD IN NORMAL FAMILIES WITH AN INCOME FROM 
 $4OO TO $7OO, CLASSIFIED BY NATIVITY AND INCOME. r 
 
 
 
 Income 
 
 
 
 *4oo-$499 
 
 *500-JS99 
 
 *6oo-$699 
 
 Native white . . 
 
 $212 
 
 $24.5 
 
 $260 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 22Q 
 
 255 
 
 276 
 
 Old Immigration : 
 Canada 
 
 228 
 
 25O 
 
 fv 
 
 267 
 
 England 
 
 21^ 
 
 257 
 
 27O 
 
 Ireland 
 
 21.1 
 
 26l 
 
 278 
 
 Sweden 
 
 217 
 
 24.8 
 
 271 
 
 Germany. . 
 
 224. 
 
 254. 
 
 277 
 
 New Immigration: 
 Austria-Hungary 
 Russia 
 
 252 
 
 27.5 
 
 *O4- 
 
 267 
 
 27*1 
 
 / / 
 
 289 
 2QT 
 
 Italy 
 
 214. 
 
 */O 
 275 
 
 ^91 
 26l 
 
 
 
 
 * u o 
 
 The lowest expenditures for food within the same income 
 group were found among native white workmen with 
 incomes under $500 and above $600; in the middle group 
 the lowest place was held by the Italians, the next to the 
 lowest by native white Americans. The highest expendi- 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table V D. 
 PP- 560-563. 
 
The Standard of Living 263 
 
 tures were reported by the Russians in the two groups with 
 incomes of $500 and over. In the lowest income group the 
 highest expenditure for food was found among natives of 
 Austria-Hungary, while the Russians were on a par with 
 the English and above the Irish, the Canadians and the 
 Germans. In the other two groups, the natives of Austria- 
 Hungary expended more than the native Americans and 
 more than any of the "old immigrants." The Italians 
 expended more than the native Americans in the two 
 extreme groups, and only $10.00 less per year, i. e., three 
 cents a day less per family in the middle group. 
 It is possible that the higher expenditure for food among the 
 "undesirable" races is accounted for by the size of the 
 family, but the earnings of the head of the family must 
 cover the expense of supporting all its members. It is 
 therefore, the total expense rather than the average per in- 
 dividual that may, by supposition, affect the rate of wages. 
 Still, if we turn to the comparative table of the same 
 report in which the expenditure for food of native and 
 foreign families is reduced to a uniform basis of units of 
 consumption, 1 we observe the same tendency as shown by 
 the comparison of total expenditures. We learn from that 
 table: 
 
 (1) That among the families having no children the 
 natives of Russia expended $145.24 per one hundred units 
 of consumption, while the natives of the United States 
 expended only $119.85; 
 
 (2) That among the families with two children, the 
 Russians expended $107.35 as against $95.24 expended by 
 Americans ; 
 
 (3) That among families with three children, the 
 average expense of the Russians was $108.11, whereas 
 the Americans expended only $85.06; 
 
 (4) That an Italian family with one child expended 
 on an average $124.73, while an American family of the 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commission of Labor, Table V D., 
 
 p. 102. 
 
264 Immigration and Labor 
 
 same size was contented with $109.94, a* 1 English family 
 with $107.19, and a Norwegian with $87.53; 
 
 (5) That an Austro-Hungarian family without children 
 or with one child expended more for food than a Scotch 
 family of the same size; 
 
 (6) That an Austro-Hungarian family with two children 
 needed $i 17.22, while a native American family of the same 
 size could exist on $95.24, and an English family on $105.86; 
 
 (7) That an Austro-Hungarian family with three 
 children, expended $98.65 per one hundred units of con- 
 sumption as compared with $85.00 expended by an average 
 American family of the same size, and with $85.20 expended 
 by an average English family; 
 
 (8) That an Austro-Hungarian family with four or 
 five children, expended more than a Scotch family; 
 
 (9) That the Scotch were in every group inferior to 
 the Russians; 
 
 (10) That English families with less than five children 
 had a lower expenditure for food than Russian families 
 of equal size. 1 
 
 These budgets have been quoted here as the best evidence 
 that has been collected on the comparative standards of 
 living of native and foreign-bora wage-earners. Still, 
 large as the number of individual families included in the 
 canvass of the Bureau of Labor may look at a superficial 
 glance, it affords too narrow a foundation for nice distinc- 
 tions. Food expenditures vary with the size and the 
 income of the family, and with geographical location 
 affecting the prices of food-stuffs. If the food expendi- 
 tures are to be compared by nationality, under uniform 
 conditions as to location, size of family, and income, some 
 of the groups must be so minute as to preclude the possibility 
 of any reliable generalizations. The last table commented 
 upon may serve as an illustration; among the foreign 
 nationalities, there is no group of more than seventeen 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commission of Labor, p. 631, Table 
 VIE. 
 
The Standard of Living 265 
 
 families, while most of the groups contain less than ten 
 families, and twenty-one consist of only one family. Varia- 
 tions in individual cases, however, are very wide. The 
 only conclusion that is warranted by such statistics as are 
 available is a negative one, viz., that the existence of a 
 race standard of living determining the rate of wages for 
 every race is not proven. 1 "The actual standard that 
 prevails is set primarily by the wages paid and the prices 
 charged." 2 
 
 E. Clothing 
 
 In no other respect is the assimilation of the immigrant 
 accomplished so rapidly as in the matter of dress. The 
 mandates of Herbert Spencer's "ceremonial government" 
 cannot be disobeyed. "Many of the recent immigrants," 
 says the Immigration Commission, "still have some articles 
 of clothing which they brought with them from Europe. 
 Most of their clothing, however, practically all, is made in 
 this country and purchased by them here." 3 The prices 
 which the alien workman must pay in an American depart- 
 ment store for shoes and clothes are fixed, not by his im- 
 
 1 In a later work, published in 1917, the chief expert of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission seems to have come to recognize that the standard of 
 living of the new immigrants is not lower than, but different from, that 
 of the native wage-earners. Whereas the immigrant seeks primarily 
 physical comfort, with the sophisticated American worker the con- 
 ventional plays a conspicuous part in his family budget. To put it in 
 Professor Lauck's words: 
 
 "It is significant to note that all newer immigrants spend a greater 
 proportion of their total expenditures for food than do the native wage- 
 earners. This seems to be due to the fact that their standard of living 
 is less subject to demands created by desires other than for food. In a 
 sense, their standard is more elemental. They are more free to satisfy 
 their natural physical wants, and less restricted than native wage- 
 earners, by the pressure of other wants upon their income. In the 
 selection of their diet it seems to be the consensus of observations that the 
 newer immigrant has the advantage over the native wage-earners." W. Jett 
 Lauck and Edgar Sydenstricker: The Condition of Labor in American 
 Industries, p. 288. 
 
 * Chapin, loc. cit. t pp. 249-250. 
 
 8 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 8l. 
 
266 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ported individual or racial psychology, but by the Ameri- 
 can manufacturer, the American railway manager, and the 
 American department store proprietor, every one of them 
 eager to make an American profit, in order to maintain an 
 American standard of living for himself. 
 
 The Immigration Commission secured the transcripts of 
 store accounts, which showed that the prices paid for wear- 
 ing apparel by immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe were the same as those advertised in Washington, 
 D. C., by the department stores and tailor shops catering 
 to the trade of government clerks. 1 
 
 The United States Bureau of Labor has published com- 
 parative statistics showing for each nationality the average 
 annual expenditure for clothing. It can be seen at a glance 
 that the expenditure for clothing among the native, as well as 
 among the foreign-born, increases with the increase of their 
 earnings. 2 Whether, or not, the wage-earner's standard of 
 living determines his wages, *. e., whether, or not, he is paid 
 higher wages because he wears better clothes, it is self-evident 
 that his ability to buy clothes is limited by his earnings. 
 A comparison of race standards in the matter of clothing 
 must therefore be made for workmen of the same earning 
 capacity. Table 80 on page 267 follows the arrangement 
 of Table 79. 
 
 It can be seen from Table 80 that in each of the in- 
 come groups the variations of expenditure by race are 
 confined within very narrow limits, the margin between the 
 highest and lowest expenditure not exceeding $10.00 a year. 
 It is evident that such a margin is too small to produce an 
 appreciable effect upon the rate of wages. 3 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, pp. 81, 84. 
 
 * Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table V,D. 
 
 * It must be borne in mind, that the numbers of families in each group 
 being small, the variations may be due to differences in the size of the 
 families, in geographical location, etc. ~Even the earnings may vary 
 within each income group as much as $99.00 per year. Some allowance 
 must be made for the inaccuracy of the figures, inasmuch as they are all 
 mere estimates. 
 
The Standard of Living 
 
 TABLE 80. 
 
 267 
 
 EXPENDITURE FOR CLOTHING IN NORMAL FAMILIES OF UNSKILLED 
 LABORERS, CLASSIFIED BY INCOME AND NATIVITY. x 
 
 Country of birth 
 
 
 Income 
 
 
 
 ^400-1499 
 
 $500-*599 
 
 J6oo-|6 9 9 
 
 Native 
 
 $53 
 
 $66 
 
 $79 
 
 Foreign-born, generally . . . 
 Old Immigration: 
 
 53 
 
 57 
 
 63 
 
 61 
 
 78 
 82 
 
 England 
 
 58 
 
 67 
 
 75 
 
 
 ci 
 
 61 
 
 7-1 
 
 Sweden 
 
 48 
 
 64 
 
 78 
 
 Germany 
 
 52 
 
 63 
 
 80 
 
 New Immigration : 
 Austria-Hungary. . . . 
 Russia 
 
 57 
 
 C2 
 
 6l 
 64 
 
 82 
 
 74. 
 
 Italv . . 
 
 C2 
 
 cy 
 
 7-1 
 
 
 
 
 
 F. Savings 
 
 The expenses of a normal family for housing, food, and 
 clothing amount in the aggregate to about three fourths 
 of the total expenditure for all objects. 2 The preceding 
 analysis has shown that the variations of these principal 
 items of a workingman's budget are not affected by race. 
 Table 81 on page 268 points in the same direction. It can 
 be seen from the comparative figures that the average wage- 
 earner's family of every nationality lives practically up to 
 its income. A very small margin is left for savings. But 
 while the native workman may save or spend at pleasure, the 
 newly-arrived immigrant must save money. 
 
 " Before the immigrant can realize any return from his 
 labor in the form of American wages, he must incur the 
 following expense or indebtedness, for even if one or all 
 costs are prepaid for him by relative, friend, or other person, 
 he eventually pays them all by deductions from his wages 
 or otherwise: 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, pp. 560-563. 
 
 3 Ibid., p. 581, Table 5K. 
 
268 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 81. 
 
 SURPLUS OF INCOME OVER EXPENDITURE OF NORMAL FAMILIES; 
 CLASSIFIED BY COUNTRY OF BIRTH. 1 
 
 Country of birth 
 
 Amount 
 
 Per cent of income 
 
 Native 
 
 $ 37 
 
 5.6 
 
 
 26 
 
 4. 1 
 
 Old immigration: 
 
 41 
 
 6 I 
 
 England 
 
 40 
 
 5.8 
 
 
 38 
 
 4.. 2 
 
 Germany 
 
 2^ 
 
 3.6 
 
 
 I5 
 
 2.6 
 
 New Immigration: 
 Italy 
 
 2* 
 
 4.6 
 
 
 14. 
 
 2. 5 
 
 
 A 
 
 0.6 
 
 
 
 
 1. Cost of preparation at his home in Europe for the 
 journey. 
 
 2 . Cost of transportation from his home to the European 
 seaport. 
 
 3. Cost of emigrant head tax to his Government. 
 
 4. Cost of immigrant head tax to the United States 
 Government. 
 
 5. Cost of steamship transportation, European port to 
 the United States. 
 
 6. Cost of labor agency for securing employment at 
 port of entry, if used. 
 
 7. Cost of transportation, United States port of entry 
 to place of employment. 
 
 8. Cost of living from port of entry to place of destina- 
 tion." 2 
 
 The cost of items 3-5 and 7 is further on estimated at 
 $40.00 for a single Italian, Slav, or Hungarian immigrant. 
 If the immigrant has left wife and children in his native 
 country, he must save money to pay their passage. In 
 order to meet these demands the immigrant must curtail 
 his expenses for the necessities of life. This is accomplished 
 
 1 Eighteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 581, 
 Tables V, J and K. 
 
 9 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 72, pp. 411-412. 
 
The Standard of Living 269 
 
 in various ways. Living in crowded tenements is one of 
 them. Co-operative boarding, which has been given the 
 odious name of "the boarding boss system," enables the 
 Slav laborer to reduce his board bill much below the price 
 the individualistic Anglo-Saxon has to pay in a boarding 
 house, though, as has been shown, the fare under the co- 
 operative system is at least as wholesome and abundant as 
 in an average boarding house. 
 
 The fact, however, that the immigrant who has no family 
 in the United States is at first content to deny himself many 
 comforts does not warrant the apprehension that he will 
 be satisfied with a wage just sufficient to provide the bare 
 necessities of life. The Italian railroad laborer who sub- 
 sists on vegetables does not work for the mere price of his 
 vegetables, but saves about 80 per cent of his wages. 
 "Ninety-five per cent of the Italian laborers save from 
 $25.00 to $30.00 of their wages per month. For eight 
 months' work this would amount to over $200 per man." 1 
 It is a matter of general knowledge that large sums of 
 money are annually sent home by the immigrants. A 
 member of the Immigration Commission who visited a 
 Greek mountain village from which two hundred immigrants 
 had gone to the United States was told that each of the 
 men sent back about $200 annually. 2 It was learned 
 from the records of a post-office in a township of Russian 
 Poland that thirty-seven workmen who had immigrated 
 from that township to the United States sent home in 1903 
 the sum of 47,862 roubles, i. e., an average of $665 per 
 emigrant. 3 That these are not isolated cases is indicated 
 by the number of international money orders sent from the 
 United States to Europe, which averaged, in 1907-1909, 
 about three millions a year. 4 Moreover, hundreds of 
 
 1 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 72, pp. 469-470, 477, 481. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4 (in press). 
 
 a Reports of the Warsaw Statistical Committee, Bulletin XXII. K. B. 
 Vobly: General Analysis of the Statistics of Migration of Workers for 
 Temporary Employment and of the Statistics of Emigration, p. 29. 
 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 37, p. 280. 
 
270 Immigration and Labor 
 
 thousands of immigrants annually return home, and their 
 passage must be paid ,out of their savings. The total 
 amount sent abroad by immigrants in the year 1907 is 
 estimated by the Immigration Commission at $275,000,000. 
 This estimate "does not take into account the large sums 
 carried abroad by returning immigrants." 1 
 
 A better idea of the average amount an immigrant man- 
 ages to save from his wages can be gained from the economic 
 effects produced by the flow of American money into the 
 rural districts of Southern and Eastern Europe. In Greece 
 
 much of the money sent home by emigrants is for the payment of old 
 debts and cancellation of mortgages, a considerable part ... for 
 deposits, loans, the purchases of real estate or the improvement of 
 property already owned. . . . Many houses were . . . built by money 
 sent back by emigrants. . . . Usury is receding, fleeing from the 
 glitter of abundant gold which has inundated towns and villages. . . . 
 Nor is it surprising that the rate of interest should have fallen from 
 20, 15, and 10 per cent to 6 and 5 per cent.* 
 
 Li Southern Italy, those who return from America pur- 
 chase a house with a small estate. In Austria-Hungary, 
 the enormous influx of money goes partly to pay old debts 
 and to bring over families, but most of it to support rela- 
 tives at home, to invest in land, to build homes, to make 
 improvements, and to buy agricultural machinery. "The 
 desire of the returning emigrant to invest in land has led to 
 a considerable increase in its value, particularly in Croatia, 
 Galicia, and the Slovak district of Hungary. ... In 
 Galicia the buying of large estates by associations of 
 emigrants has become a common practice. Very often 
 from 50,000 to 90,000 acres a year are thus bought up and 
 subdivided among the peasant purchasers. The money is 
 either contributed from the savings of the associated 
 peasants or borrowed from friends who are still in America. ' ' 
 Reports from all emigration countries concur in the state- 
 ment that the standard of living~of the peasants who have 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 37, p. 277. 
 Ibid., vol. 4, p. 413. 
 
The Standard of Living 271 
 
 returned from the United States is above that of their 
 neighbors. The roomy cottages built by them with money 
 earned in the United States are in striking contrast with the 
 surrounding poverty and dirt. In short, according to the 
 Immigration Commission, the savings of the immigrants 
 " are an important factor in promoting the general economic 
 welfare of several European countries. " It is evident that 
 the wages of the immigrants must needs be sufficient to 
 enable them to invest hundreds of millions of dollars in 
 the uplifting of the economic conditions of their native 
 countries, after paying American prices for all necessities 
 of life. Viewed solely with an eye to the economic interests 
 of the American wage-earner, the efforts of the average 
 immigrant from Southern and Eastern Europe "to live 
 upon the basis of minimum cheapness, and to save as much 
 as possible," at the sacrifice of comfort, 1 is a matter of no 
 concern to his competitors in the labor market. Whether 
 he spends his wages on rent, food, and clothing, or saves 
 his money to buy steamship tickets for his family, whether 
 he deposits his savings in a local bank, or sends them to 
 his parents for improving the home farm, his wants in one 
 case are as great and as imperative as in the other, and he 
 must demand a wage which will enable him to satisfy 
 them. Furthermore, contrary to learned opinion, a wage- 
 earner who is able to save four fifths of his earnings need 
 not accept "employment on the terms offered or suffer from 
 actual want, " for he can live four months on the savings of 
 one, and is therefore "in a position to take exception to 
 wages or working conditions" 2 a great deal more readily 
 than the native wage-earner who lives to the limit of his 
 income. This fact has been proved more than once in 
 recent years by the long drawn out strikes of Southern and 
 Eastern European mine and factory operatives. 
 
 There is a tendency to view with disapproval "the send- 
 ing back to the old country of the savings of the immigrant," 
 upon the old Mercantilist theory that every dollar invested 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 183-184. a Ibid. 
 
272 Immigration and Labor 
 
 by him in his home country is a loss to the United States: 
 "America, should have the productive influence of not only 
 the labor but also of the capital made from the savings." 1 
 The same objection certainly applies with far greater force 
 to the investment of American capital in foreign industrial 
 enterprises. One important fact is overlooked in this 
 objection, viz., that the money which is invested in the 
 home farm provides for the relatives of the immigrant who 
 stay in the old country. Were that money invested in the 
 United States they would have to be brought over to the 
 United States. While the capital invested in the United 
 States would be increased, the supply of labor would like- 
 wise be increased. Money being dearer in Europe than in 
 the United States, the savings that are ample to provide 
 employment for the immigrants' relatives at home, would 
 be insufficient, if invested in American industries, to keep 
 an equal number of persons employed in the United States. 
 Their immigration would accordingly tend to increase the 
 supply of labor out of proportion to the demand. 
 
 The only economic interests affected in a real, not in an 
 imaginary way, by the thrifty habits ("the low standard 
 of living") of the recent immigrant, is the mercantile 
 business which seeks the trade of the wage-earner as a 
 consumer. With many manufacturing and mining concerns 
 the commissary is an important part of the industry. 
 
 In fact, [says the Immigration Commission] according to the 
 statements of some of the small operators, commissaries as a rule return 
 not only a 20 per cent net profit in normal times to the company, but 
 the system goes so far as to largely determine the race of employees. 
 In certain cases it was stated that negroes were preferred because their 
 improvident habits prevented them from being able to live on a cash 
 income, paid monthly, and thus forced them to draw their wages weekly, 
 and even daily, in the form of commissary checks or store credits. 
 Currency payments were made monthly partly for this purpose. As a 
 result, the negroes are always a little in debt to the commissaries. . . . 
 Their wants are confined to the supply-x>f goods furnished by the com- 
 missaries, with the exception of whiskey, and they have no funds for 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t p. 16. 
 
The Standard of Living 273 
 
 any other purpose than that of bare subsistence .... For the same 
 reason these employers do not encourage immigrant laborers, and in 
 some cases refuse to employ them altogether. The immigrant exhibits 
 a strong tendency to get his wages in cash and to live on the lowest 
 level possible to maintain subsistence. . . . He seeks the cheapest 
 places. ... A careful and detailed inquiry into a comparison of 
 prices in the commissaries and in the city markets and groceries 
 revealed a slight increase in the general run of prices in the former over 
 the latter. 1 
 
 The Croatians are good livers in comparison with the other foreign 
 races, and they do not stint themselves in food or drink [say Professors 
 Jenks and Lauck]. Although extravagant, they do not, however, 
 spend as much as the negroes, who loiter about the commissaries 
 looking for something for which to spend their money. The Croatians 
 know what they want and buy it freely, but if there is a surplus of their 
 wages it is saved. The Italians, living as they do, very cheaply, buy 
 little from the commissaries. In a general way the laborers are required 
 to patronize the commissaries 3 . . . . 
 
 From the point of view of the proprietor of the commis- 
 sary store, an immigrant with a "low standard of living," 
 who buys in the cheapest store, or saves his money instead 
 of leaving it in the commissary, is, naturally enough, 
 "undesirable." 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission^ vol. 9, p. 190. 
 * Jenks and Lauck, he. tit., p. 176. 
 
CHAPTER XI 
 
 HOME OWNERSHIP 
 
 of homes by wage-earners has been 
 advocated as a proposition of practical social reform, 
 ever since the condition of labor has been recognized as 
 a distinct social problem. The Immigration Commission 
 has given a prominent place in its investigation to home 
 ownership among immigrant races on the ground that "the 
 proportion of the families in a given group of workmen who 
 live in homes owned by themselves may fairly be regarded 
 as an indication, at least, of the social and industrial 
 progress of the group." 1 
 
 The Commission fully realizes "that the wage-earner is 
 living and working in a large urban or industrial center 
 where the acquisition of real estate is beyond his resources, " 
 while in small mining towns "the industrial worker is 
 practically not permitted to buy a home, but must live in a 
 house owned by the operating company." 2 The mining 
 companies find it "a better policy to retain the houses 
 because of large profits arising from rent payments and for 
 the additional reason that mine workers may be evicted in 
 the event of a strike." 3 Moreover, the ownership of a 
 home, even when within the reach of the wage-earner, 
 often does not pay as an investment : 
 
 If an employee should invest in a home near his work and for any 
 reason he should be thrown out of work, the property would not be 
 valuable, because there are no other industries near in which he could 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, p. 267. 
 * Ibid., vol. I, p. 467. a Ibid., vol. 6, p. 452. 
 
 274 
 
Home Ownership 275 
 
 find employment. The coal mines often have periods when work is 
 irregular, or suspend operations for months at a time, which facts tend 
 to make coal-mining labor migratory. 1 
 
 These conditions are not peculiar to coal mining alone, 
 but exist generally. 2 Nevertheless, after all that is said, 
 the Commission regards "the number and percentage of 
 families owning their homes," as indications of "racial 
 inclinations toward the acquisition of property." 3 It is 
 noted that "the recent immigrant has no property or other 
 restraining interests which attach him to a community," 
 and the fact is officially recorded among the "salient char- 
 acteristics of the recent immigrant labor supply," 4 This is 
 an error. As far back as 1878, a noted New York philanthro- 
 pist spoke in almost the same terms of the immigrants of his 
 day, who were mostly Irish and Germans: 
 
 They do not own the house nor any part of it, nor have any interest 
 in it. ... The general effect of the system is the existence of a prole- 
 taire class, who have no interest in the permanent well-being of the 
 community, who have no sense of home, and who live without any deep 
 root in the soil. 5 
 
 It is obvious that the subject of home ownership is viewed 
 in these opinions from the standpoint of a middle-class 
 resident of a rural community, not from that of a wage- 
 earner. 6 A farmer, a shopkeeper, or a professional man, is 
 
 l Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, p. 206. 
 
 8 An English writer who would encourage "the acquirement by work- 
 ingmen of their homes," recognizes that "a difficulty exists in the fact 
 that a large portion of the working classes are migrating, owing to the 
 changes and irregularities of their means of livelihood." T. L. Worth- 
 ington: Dwellings of the People, (26. edition, 1901), p. 60. 
 
 ^Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , p. 467. This view is ex- 
 pressed with all due "qualifications," "reservations," and "limitations." 
 
 *Ibid., pp. 498, 500 "This characteristic has both a good and a bad 
 influence .... Probably, the bad effect of this characteristic is greater 
 than the good, all things considered." Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit, p. 185. 
 
 ^Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 459. 
 
 *"The idea that the working man must buy his dwelling rests upon 
 the reactionary conception that the condition created by modern large 
 scale industry is a pathological degeneration, and that society must 
 be forcibly steered against the stream which has been running for over 
 
276 Immigration and Labor 
 
 by the nature of his occupation attached to a certain com- 
 munity. With him the ownership of a home is a profitable 
 investment. Considered, however, from the point of view 
 of the wage-earner who lives "in a town dominated by a 
 single industry, home ownership would seriously hinder his 
 defense of his rights in a disagreement with his employers." l 
 In a small town, where many of the workmen own their homes 
 
 trade-unionism means but little [to them]. If, however, trade-unionism 
 becomes a factor and organization follows, with accompanying demands 
 for shorter hours and more pay, these men would think long and well of 
 their little homes . . . before engaging upon a strike, the outcome of 
 which may possibly mean the loss of many things they greatly prize. 
 It seems that the employers have the upper hand. 8 
 
 A wage-earner, on the contrary, who has no property 
 interests attaching him to a certain community, is "free 
 to follow the best industrial inducements." 5 
 
 Inasmuch, however, as the ownership of a home is re- 
 garded "as a mark of thrift" 4 it is instructive to compare 
 the extent of home ownership at present and in the past, be- 
 fore "the Slav invasion," and still earlier, before immigration 
 became a social factor in the United States. 
 
 As early as 1790, when Boston had a population of 18,320, 
 the average number of families to each house in the town 
 was 1.46, which means that at least one third of all Boston 
 families lived in rented houses, even on the assumption 
 that all one-family houses were occupied by their owners 
 and that in the two-family houses one dwelling was occupied 
 by the owner. Half a century later, at the city census of 
 1845, the proportion of home owners in Boston was found 
 to be only 17.5 per cent. 4 The population of Boston was 
 then only 114,000, and the percentage of foreign-born and 
 
 a century, into a condition . . . which is generally nothing but an ideal- 
 ized restoration of the moribund small handicraft." Friedrich Engels: 
 Zur Wohnungsfrage. 
 
 1 Streightoff, loc. cit., p. 84. Pratt, loc. tit., p. 99. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 500. 
 
 4 Ibid., vol. 6, p. 451. * Census of Boston, 1845, p. 55. 
 
Home Ownership 277 
 
 their children born in Boston was 32.61. In other words, 
 there were 67.39 per cent of native Americans of native 
 parentage, of whom at most only one fourth owned their 
 homes, even if there was not a single home owner among the 
 foreign-born. The percentage of home owners has since 
 slightly increased, as shown in the following table: 
 
 TABLE 82. 
 
 PER CENT OF HOME OWNERS IN THE POPULATION OF BOSTON, 1845-1900.* 
 
 Year Per cent 
 
 1845 17-5 
 
 1890 18.43 
 
 1900 18.9 
 
 The most thorough-going statistical study of home owner- 
 ship in the United States was made at the census of 1890. 
 The data for that year reflect the standard of living of 
 native Americans at a time when it could not have been 
 affected by immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 It will be seen from Table 83 on page 278 that of all 
 American householders of native stock who were living in 
 cities with a population of from 50,000 to 250,000 in 1890, 
 only a little over one fourth owned their homes; in larger 
 cities the percentage was still smaller. And it must be 
 borne in mind that these percentages relate to people in all 
 walks of life, not to wage-earners alone. The prevailing 
 "American standard" in cities is accordingly the standard 
 of a tenant, not that of a home owner. 
 
 1 Census of Boston, pp. 26 and 37. The percentage of persons born of 
 foreign parents in the United States outside of Boston could not have 
 affected the situation, as appears from the fact that of the native children 
 of foreign parents there were 10,105 under the age of 20 and only 80 over 
 the age of 20. Evidently, immigration was new and the native children 
 of foreign parents were still very young. 
 
 a Report on Farms and Homes in the United States at the XI. Census, 
 p. 32. XII. Census, Population, Part II., Table CVL, p. ccv. 
 
 a The population of Suffolk County representing the economic, though 
 not the municipal, Boston, included 19.36 per cent home-owners. 
 
2 7 8 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 83. 
 
 PERCENTAGE OF NATIVE WHITE HOME OWNERS TO ALL OCCUPANTS, 
 
 CLASSIFIED BY PARENT NATIVITY, IN CITIES WITH A POPULATION 
 
 OF 50,000 AND OVER. 1 
 
 Population 
 
 Per cent of 1 
 
 tome owners 
 
 
 Native parentage 
 
 Foreign parentage 
 
 50,000 to 250,000 
 
 27.6 
 
 26.4 
 
 250,000 and over 
 
 21.5 
 
 17.7 
 
 
 
 
 This fact is not due, however, to a racial disinclination 
 of the American of native stock toward the acquisition of 
 property, but to the fact that the value of a house is beyond 
 the reach of the majority of householders. The proof will 
 be found in Table 84: 
 
 TABLE 84. 
 
 PERCENTAGES OF HOME OWNERS CLASSIFIED BY VALUE OF HOMES, 1890." 
 
 
 United 
 
 Cities classifie 
 
 d by population 
 
 Value 
 
 States 
 
 8,000 to 100,000 
 
 100,000 and over 
 
 Under $500 
 
 O.6^ 
 
 O.2I 
 
 O.O4 
 
 $500 and under $1000 
 
 3.56 
 
 2.46 
 
 0.61 
 
 $1000 and under $2500 
 
 17.41 
 
 17.04. 
 
 Q.24 
 
 $2500 and under $5000 
 
 22.^5 
 
 2e Q"* 
 
 17.05 
 
 $5000 and over 
 
 "oo 
 S6.o^ 
 
 ^46 
 
 72.l6 
 
 
 
 
 
 More than one half of all homes in the United States were 
 valued in 1890 at $5000 and over; in cities with a population 
 of 100,000 and over the proportion of homes of the same 
 value was nearly three fourths. 
 
 The relative number of home owners decreased with 
 the growth of the density of population and the resulting 
 
 1 Farms and Homes, XI. Census, Table 73, p. 204. 
 ' Ibid., Table 39, p. 87 
 
Home Ownership 
 
 279 
 
 increase of the value of real estate, as shown in Table 85, 
 where all States and Territories are divided into two areas : 
 
 I. With ratio of home owners to total families above the 
 average for the United States; 
 
 II. With ratio of home owners to total families below 
 the average for the United States. 
 
 TABLE 85. 
 
 HOME OWNERSHIP AND VALUE OF REAL ESTATE IN AREAS WITH RATIO 
 OF HOME OWNERS TO TOTAL FAMILIES ABOVE (I) AND BELOW (II) 
 THE AVERAGE, 
 
 Areas 
 
 Per cent of home 
 owners 
 
 Population 
 per square mile 
 
 Average value per home 
 (including incumbrances) 
 
 I 
 II 
 
 46.34 
 30-53 
 
 12 
 
 53 
 
 $ 2656 
 
 3828 
 
 To be sure, some of the homes were incumbered (three 
 eighths of all homes in cities with a population of 100,000 
 and over, and less in smaller cities and towns 2 ), but the 
 average incumbrance in the United States covered only 37.7 
 per cent of the value. 3 The average equity of the owner 
 ranged from $3200 in cities with a population of 100,000 
 and over, down to $1400 in settlements of less than 8000 
 inhabitants. 4 
 
 Age is an important factor in home ownership ; under the 
 age of forty-five the majority were tenants (see Diagram 
 XVII) . s This was the rule in every section of the country, 
 in those where the percentage of foreign-born was high, as 
 well as in those where it was low. The percentage of home- 
 owners increases with advancing years, and it is only in old 
 age that a majority become home-owners. It takes a 
 lifetime of savings to acquire a home. Now it must be 
 remembered that most of the immigrants are under the 
 
 1 Farms and Homes, XI. Census, Table 16, p. 42. 
 
 2 Ibid., Table 14, p:34. 
 
 J Ibid., Tables 104-106, pp. 421-428. Ibid., Table 38, pp. 83-86. 
 s Ibid., p. 224, Diagram 32. 
 
280 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 DIAGRAM XVII. PER CENT RATIO OF HOME OWNERS AND TENANTS TO 
 
 UNDER 5 YEARS. 
 15, TO td 
 
 UNITED STATES. 
 
 o 10 to SO 40 So *0 la to -90 
 
 30 
 
 45 
 50 
 
 55 
 
 34 
 39 
 44 
 49 
 
 59 
 
 60 YEARS* OVER: 
 
 YSSSSSSSSS/S/SS/SA 
 
 TMC 58 CITIES or So.ooo POPULATION 
 
 UNDER 25 YEARS. 
 15 TO *9 
 
 E 
 
 40 
 
 Owners 
 
 Tenants 
 
 age of forty-five on arrival. It was found in 1890, when 
 immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe was insig- 
 nificant, that "by far the principal portion of the foreign- 
 born owners of farms and homes have been in this country 
 fifteen years and over." 1 Of all industrial workers from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, however, who were covered 
 by the investigation of the Immigration Commission, only 
 from 0.9 per cent (Roumanians) to 18.2 per cent (Russian 
 Jews) had been in the United States fifteen years or over. 2 
 According to the standard set by the immigrants fromNorth- 
 
 and Homes, XI. Census, p. 163. 
 * Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit. t p. 477. 
 
ALL HOME FAMILIES, CLASSIFIED BY AGE PERIODS AND BY GEOGRAPHI- 
 CAL DIVISIONS, 1890. 
 
 NORTH CENTRAL. 
 
 UNDK*5 YEARS. 
 15 TO 19 
 
 34 
 33 * 33 - 
 40 - 44 - 
 45 - 43 " 
 30-34 
 55 - 53 
 *0 YEARS &0VER; 
 
 30 40 
 
 *o TO. 90. ft 10* 
 
 UNDER JtS YEARS. 
 *3 TO 13 
 30 ^ 34 
 33 3d 
 
 WESTERN. 
 
 ,0 10 to JO 40 50 *0 70 
 
 90 100 
 
 NORTH ATLANTIC. 
 
 o 10 fiO SO 40 SO 60 70 *0 90 U 
 
 Tenants 
 
 281 
 
282 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ern and Western Europe, the overwhelming majority of the 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe had not 
 been long enough in the United States to have raised suf- 
 ficient funds for buying real estate. 
 
 The inference drawn from the statistics of home owner- 
 ship in 1890 by the authors of the census report "is that 
 home tenancy is increasing in the whole country as the 
 urban population becomes numerically a more important 
 element of the population." 1 The old American standard 
 which found its expression in the one-family residence 
 retreats before the apartment house. This tendency 
 asserts itself even among the well-to-do who could afford 
 to buy a home for the rental they pay for a fashionable 
 apartment. The rate of the change can be observed in a 
 city like Washington, which has but a small foreign popula- 
 tion. 2 A count of the houses and apartments advertised 
 in the Washington Star on the last Saturday in July, 1900 
 and 1910, for rent to white tenants brought the following 
 results: 
 
 TABLE 86. 
 
 NUMBER OF HOUSES AND APARTMENTS ADVERTISED FOR RENT TO 
 
 WHITE TENANTS IN WASHINGTON, D. C., ON THE LAST 
 
 SATURDAY IN JULY, IQOO AND IQIO. 
 
 For rent 
 
 1900 
 
 1910 
 
 Per cent of increase 
 
 One-family houses 
 
 882 
 
 1169 
 
 j- 
 
 Apartment houses 
 
 64 
 
 580 
 
 806 
 
 
 
 
 
 The number of apartment houses which advertised apart- 
 ments for rent increased ninefold within ten years, while 
 the number of one-family houses increased only by one third. 
 
 1 Farms and Homes, XL Census, p. 54. 
 
 3 The ratio of the foreign-born and their children to the population of 
 Washington, D. C., was only 20.6 per cent in 1900 and 21 per cent in 
 1910. XIII. Census, vol. i, p. 150. 
 
Home Ownership 283 
 
 It is clear from this example that the tendency toward the 
 apartment house or tenement house has no connection with 
 immigration. It is in line with the general tendency 
 toward concentration characteristic of modern times. 1 
 
 1 This has come to be recognized by industrial experts. In the 
 opinion of Mr. Henry Wright, an architect who during the war was 
 town planner of Emergency Fleet Corporation towns and has since 
 made a study of housing conditions for the community planning 
 committee of the American Institute of Architects, the time has come 
 for "a scientific revolution of our methods of building houses." Speak- 
 ing of the present housing situation to a writer for. the Globe of New 
 York, he was quoted (in the issue of June I, 1920) to have said: 
 
 " ' Own Your Own Home' campaigns to-day are essentially buncombe. 
 They cannot provide houses for the laboring classes; under present 
 conditions no one belonging to the laboring classes can afford to 'own 
 his own home.' . . . We must do away with the old sales system and its 
 single lot, single family house, and surplus street, and come to group 
 and multi-family house building with its savings of billions for the 
 country in street maintenance, constructional costs, and proportion 
 of land to houses. " 
 
CHAPTER XII 
 
 EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES 
 
 THAT wages in many occupations are barely sufficient 
 to provide for the necessities of life, has been estab- 
 lished by all investigations of the cost of living. That 
 unskilled labor receives a lower wage than skilled labor, is 
 a truism. That the standard of living of unskilled laborers 
 must be lower than that of skilled mechanics, is the neces- 
 sary consequence of the difference in the rates of their 
 compensation. Inasmuch, however, as the skilled me- 
 chanics are mostly native Americans and older immigrant^, 
 whereas the unskilled laborers are mostly new immigrants, 
 the average man with a prejudice against the foreigner 
 overlooks the difference in the grade of the service rendered, 
 and jumps to the conclusion that the American mechanic 
 commands higher wages because he insists upon maintain- 
 ing an American standard of living, whereas the foreign 
 unskilled laborer is willing to accept lower wages, because he 
 is satisfied with a lower standard of living. 
 
 It has been shown, however, that the standard of living 
 ofjbhe^new immigrants is not lower than that of 
 
 ^ 
 
 decessors in the same grades of employment, or than that 
 of the present generation of native Americans engaged in 
 unskilled labor in the South, where there is practically 
 no competition of immigrant labor. Granting that the 
 standard of living determines the rate of wages, there is 
 no escape from the conclusion that thejyagesjof the new 
 immigrants can not be lower than those of the pasfgenera- 
 tion of immigrants wEoTm their day were engaged in un- 
 
 284 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 285 
 
 skilled labor. In other words the logical deduction from 
 the premises is, that the new immigration could not have 
 depressed the rate of wages. 
 
 On the other hand, though the standard of living of the 
 native or Americanized foreign-born wage-earners be higher 
 than that of the new immigrants, this difference is not 
 necessarily indicative of a higher rate of wages: the higher \ 
 standard may be maintained on the earnings of several 
 members of the family. 
 
 As a matter of fact, present-day industrial families in the United 
 States find it necessary to add to the earnings of the husband through 
 the employment of wives and children outside the home and the keeping 
 of boarders and lodgers within the home. The native American and 
 older immigrant employees maintain an independent form of family 
 life, but the earnings of the heads are supplemented by the wages of 
 the wives and children. On the other hand, the Southern and Eastern 
 European families have recourse to the keeping of boarders and lodgers 
 as a supplementary source of family income. . . . That contributions 
 of children are less general in the latter class of families is probably due 
 to the fact that children of these households have not in any consider- 
 able proportions reached working age. x 
 
 It is argued that the newly-arrived immigrant must have 
 work at once and is therefore eager to accept any terms: 
 
 Another salient fact in connection with the recent immigrant labor 
 supply has been the necessitous condition of the newcomers upon their 
 arrival in America's industrial communities. Immigrants from the 
 South and East of Europe have usually had but a few dollars in their 
 possession when their final destination in this country has been reached. 
 . . . Consequently, finding it absolutely imperative to engage in 
 work at once, they have not been in a position to take exception to 
 wages or working conditions, but must obtain employment on the terms 
 offered or suffer from actual want. a 
 
 Still, the investigations of the United States Bureau of 
 Labor have shown that only one half of the families of na- 
 tive American wage-earners (51.25 per cent) are able to 
 save, whereas one third (32.2 per cent) are barely able to 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 157-158, 161. 
 3 Ibid., pp. 183-184. 
 
286 Immigration and Labor 
 
 make both ends meet, and about one in every seven (15.55 
 per cent) have a deficit. x Only after the annual income of 
 the native American wage-earner with a normal family has 
 reached $700 is there a surplus left over average expenses. 2 
 Making allowance for unemployment, an annual income of 
 $700 may be taken as equivalent to about $2.50 a day, 
 which is approximately the dividing line between skilled 
 and unskilled labor. It thus appears that one half of the 
 native American wage-earners, or roughly speaking all 
 unskilled laborers, have no savings and are therefore in the 
 same "necessitous condition" as "the newcomers upon their 
 arrival": they "must obtain employment on the terms 
 offered or suffer from actual want. " The terms of competi- 
 tion are therefore not changed by the arrival of the 
 immigrant. 
 
 It is further argued that the immigrant is at a particular 
 disadvantage, being a stranger in a strange land : 
 
 The immigrant unfamiliar with American conditions, often not even 
 understanding the language in which he must make his contract, and 
 ignorant of the working methods which are new to him, while naturally 
 preferring the best that he can get, is often willing to work under 
 conditions and at wages which would not appeal to American working- 
 men, but which to him seem ample and satisfactory, because they are 
 so much better than he has ever known before. Moreover, when the 
 wage-earner is one unfamiliar, as are most immigrants, with American 
 conditions, he is likely to be eager, perhaps too eager, to secure work at 
 almost any wage above that affording a mere subsistence. Usually he 
 is not in touch with the American workingman or with trade unions, 
 and does not know what he could do by proper effort. He is not a 
 member of their trade organization, and cannot bargain through officials 
 who know the conditions. Moreover, if he is one who is expecting as 
 soon as possible to return to his home country with his savings, what he 
 dreads most of all is lack of work, and he is willing to take low wages 
 and bad working conditions, rather than be idle even for a short time 
 and see any of his savings disappear. In the large majority of cases, 
 doubtless, the immediate inducement to the emigrants to leave home and 
 sail for America comes in the form of a personal letter from friends or 
 members of their own families already in t^e United States. It is thus 
 
 1 Sixteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, p. 68. 
 3 Ibid., p. 592. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 287 
 
 that they learn of the much higher wages and the better living condi- 
 tions ; and usually they are practically sure of a job almost as soon as 
 they arrive, at wages which seem to them more than satisfactory. 1 
 
 This statement contains its own refutation. If the 
 immigrants "usually are practically sure of a job almost as 
 soon as they arrive," then there is no occasion for them 
 1 'to be eager to secure work at almost any wage, etc." 
 Since "in the large majority of cases" the immigrants come 
 in response to "a personal letter from friends or members 
 of their own families already in the United States," it is 
 erroneous to say that they are "not in touch with the 
 American workingman, " unless the term "American" 
 be used in the narrow sense of native American. But the 
 immigrant loses nothing in a pecuniary way by not being 
 in touch with the native workman, since the latter usually 
 works at a skilled trade, whereas the former in most cases 
 seeks employment as a common laborer. On the other 
 hand, in all establishments employing immigrant labor the 
 new applicant, as a rule, finds some one through whom he 
 makes his contract in his native language. It has been 
 shown in the discussion of the standard of living that the 
 new immigrant has obligations which do not permit him 
 "to work at any wage above that affording a mere subsist- 
 ence." As for affiliation with trade unions, it must be 
 borne in mind that they comprise only a small minority of 
 all wage-earners, native as well as foreign-born, and are 
 mostly confined to skilled trades, whereas most of the 
 immigrants are unskilled. Lastly, it is recognized by 
 the Immigration Commission that "it is inaccurate to 
 speak of the immigrant population as being only tempor- 
 ary in this country": most of the recent immigrants come 
 to stay. 2 IS 
 
 The object for which the Immigration Commission was 
 created was to supply statistical facts which should take 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. tit., pp. 18-19. 
 
 a See sw/>ra, p. 74. Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, 
 P- 657- 
 
288 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the place of speculation. After a study of the racial 
 composition of the operating forces in the principal indus- 
 tries, based upon information received for more than half 
 a million wage-earners in mines and manufactures, the 
 Commission discovered no evidence "that it was usual for 
 employers to engage recent immigrants at wages actually 
 lower than those prevailing at the time of their employment 
 in the industry where they were employed." 1 
 
 One of the most striking facts indicated by a comparison of the 
 earnings of the races in the different industries [say Professors Jenks 
 and Lauck] is that earning ability is more the outcome of industrial 
 opportunity or conditions of employment than of racial efficiency and 
 progress. This fact becomes evident when the average weekly earnings 
 of the members of a race, or several races, in the cotton or woolen and 
 worsted goods industry, are considered in connection with the earnings 
 of the same race or races in other industries. The Lithuanians, for 
 example, earn an average of $12.24 weekly in the manufacture of 
 agricultural implements and vehicles, $11.60 in clothing, $13.60 in 
 copper mining and smelting, $9.87 in furniture, $12.89 m iron and steel, 
 $11.98 in iron-ore mining, $9.50 in leather, $12.85 m oil refining, $10.87 
 in shoes, $10.67 ' m sugar refining, but only $7.86 in cotton and $7.97 in 
 woolen and worsted manufacturing. The same condition of affairs 
 is shown by other races in different industries. a 
 
 That the economists who directed the investigations of 
 the Immigration Commission regard it as a "striking" 
 fact that earning ability is the outcome of economic con- 
 ditions rather than of racial characteristics, indicates that 
 they expected to find the opposite, viz., that earning ability 
 was determined by racial factors.. Yet, notwithstanding 
 the "evident fact" brought to light by the investigations of 
 the Commission, that individuals of the same race, with 
 presumably the same "racial standards," are paid varying 
 rates of wages in different industries, the Commission per- 
 sists in the view that the rate of wages is determined by the 
 standard of living of the wage-earners. The statistics of 
 the Commission show that the earnings of the immigrants 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 494, 541. 
 3 Jenks and Lauck, he. cit., pp. 145-146. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 289 
 
 increase with the length of residence in the United States; 
 there is a ready explanation that "the immigrants of long 
 residence have acquired a higher standard of living and, 
 consequently, demand a higher wage." 1 It would seem 
 as though wages were regulated in accordance with the 
 communistic ideal, "to everybody according to his wants." 
 The question arises, however, why should the employer 
 grant the demand of the immigrant of long residence for a 
 higher wage when there is said to be an "oversupply" of 
 recent immigrants willing to accept "almost any wage 
 above that affording a mere subsistence"? The statistics 
 of the Commission give no answer to this question, because 
 the basis of its classification is race, not character of employ- 
 ment, each race being treated as a homogeneous unit. The 
 real explanation of the variation in wages among individuals 
 of the same race is that the immigrant of long residence 
 has advanced on the scale of occupations and is paid a 
 higher wage for a higher grade of labor. Since he receives 
 a higher wage, he has "consequently" acquired a higher 
 standard of living. 
 
 The primary cause which has determined the movement 
 of wages in the United States during the past thirty years 
 has been the introduction of labor-saving machinery. The 
 effect of the substitution of mechanical devices for human 
 skill is the displacement of the skilled mechanic by the 
 unskilled laborer. This tendency has been counteracted 
 in the United States by the expansion of industry : while the 
 ratio of skilled mechanics to the total operating force was 
 decreasing, the increasing scale of operations prevented 
 an actual reduction in numbers. The growing demand for 
 unskilled labor was supplied by immigration. 2 Of course, 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 2, p. 370. 
 
 9 Prof. Commons, in the Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., 
 p. 305, says: "In manufactures, mining, and transportation there 
 has been a rapid advance in machinery and a better organization 
 and division of labor, whereby the resources of the country are 
 made more productive. This advance in machinery and division of 
 labor often appears in itself to be a means of displacing labor and so of 
 
290 Immigration and Labor 
 
 this readjustment did not proceed without friction. While, 
 in the long run, there may have been no displacement of 
 skilled mechanics by unskilled laborers in the industrial 
 field as a whole, at certain times and places individual skilled 
 mechanics were doubtless dispensed with and had to seek 
 new employment. As the unskilled laborers who replaced 
 them were naturally engaged at lower wages, and as most 
 of them were immigrants, the change reflected itself in the 
 minds of the displaced American mechanics as substitution 
 of cheap immigrant labor for highly paid American labor. 
 The English, Scotch, Welsh, and Irish miners, e. g. t for 
 some time successfully resisted the introduction of machin- 
 ery. Their resistance was overcome by the employment of 
 Slavs and Italians. The impression was thus created that 
 the introduction of machinery was the effect of Slav and 
 Italian immigration. According to Professors Jenks and 
 Lauck, "the lack of skill and industrial training of the 
 recent immigrants in the United States has stimulated the 
 invention of mechanical methods and processes which 
 might be conducted by unskilled industrial workers as a 
 substitute for the skilled operatives formerly required." 2 
 This idea had been anticipated by Mr. Leiserson, who 
 expressed the belief that one of the effects "of the influx of 
 Slavs is that lack of intelligence makes improved machinery 
 and a perfected organization of the mining processes abso- 
 lutely essential. There is a direct connection* between 
 the increasing number of unintelligent mining laborers and 
 the use of mining machinery during the last ten or fifteen 
 years." The author is ready to accept at face value the 
 contention of the coal operators "that the scarcity of 
 intelligent labor compelled them to adopt machinery 
 wherever possible. ' ' 3 Presumably, but for the immigration 
 
 depressing wages, and such would be the case if industry as a whole were 
 not continually expanding. " 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. xxiii., xxxiv. 
 
 2 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 186-187. 
 
 William M. Leiserson: "Labor Conditions in the Mines of the Pitts- 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 291 
 
 of the "unintelligent" Slavs, American industry might 
 have gone on forever without improved machinery, and in- 
 stead of perfecting the organization of the mining processes 
 the mine operators would have encouraged the "arts and 
 crafts" movement in bituminous coal mining. 
 
 This theory ignores the elementary proposition of po- 
 litical economy, that the main object of labor-saving 
 machinery is to dispense precisely with "intelligent," i. e., 
 high-priced labor, and that, on the contrary, an abundant 
 supply of cheap labor would retard the introduction of 
 improved machinery. 1 
 
 The conditions in the coal mines of West Virginia may 
 serve as an example: "The low level of wages in 
 West Virginia may be inferred from the low rate of intro- 
 duction of machinery , ' ' says Prof. John R . Commons . This 
 fact, according to him, is of special significance because 
 
 burgh District." Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social 
 Science, March, 1909, pp. 318-319. 
 
 1 " If labor is cheap . . . somewhat more labor will be employed and 
 somewhat less machinery installed. ... If wages are high . . . more 
 machinery will be introduced and somewhat less labor employed." 
 C. J. Bullock, Assistant Professor of Political Economy in Harvard 
 University, The Elements of Economics, pp. 79-80. "Higher wages 
 for labor will induce entrepreneurs to economize in the use of 
 labor. . . . In the printing industry, for example, a rise in wages would 
 make it profitable for employing printers to use more labor-saving 
 machinery." Outlines of Economics, by Richard T. Ely, Professor of 
 Political Economy in the University of Wisconsin, revised and enlarged 
 by the author and Thomas S. Adams; MaxO. Lorenz, Ph.D., Assistant 
 Professor of Political Science in the University of Wisconsin; Allyn A. 
 Young, Ph.D., Professor of Economics in Leland Stanford Junior 
 University (New York, 1909), p. 369. "Every rise of wages will 
 have a tendency to determine the saved capital in a greater proportion 
 than before to the employment of machinery. Machinery and labor 
 are in constant competition, and the former can frequently not be 
 employed until kbor rises." David Ricardo: Principles of Political 
 Economy and Taxation (London, 1891), p. 386. "Where abundance of 
 cheap labor . . . can be obtained, . . . the development of machinery 
 has been generally slower. " John A. Hobson: The Evolution of Modern 
 Capitalism, p. 69; also p. 81. Cf. also Karl Marx: Capital, Book I., 
 Chapter XV: Machinery and Modern Industry, Sec. 2. 
 
292 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ''the miners of West Virginia are mainly native Americans, 
 who have only recently turned from home industry to 
 mining." 1 
 
 It is patent that the movement of labor from agriculture 
 to mining and manufactures would, even in the absence of 
 all immigration, have overcome the resistance of the 
 English-speaking miners to the introduction of machinery. 
 The number of mines is not fixed. New mines are con- 
 tinually being opened. The operator of a new machine- 
 equipped mine need not face the resistance of old pick- 
 miners; he can engage an entirely new force of operatives, 
 free from any traditions. His competition will ultimately 
 force the owners of old mines to introduce machinery or 
 go out of business. The resistance of English-speaking 
 miners might have some time been strong enough to prevent 
 the introduction of machinery, but at no time could it 
 have forced a mine operator to run his mine at a loss. The 
 shutting down of the unprofitable mines would have put 
 an end to the resistance of the pick-miners. Absence of 
 immigration might have retarded the growth of American 
 industry, but it could not have checked the introduction of 
 machinery. 
 
 Machinery has so radically changed the technique of all 
 industries that a comparison between past and present 
 wages is beset with extreme difficulties. Many old occu- 
 pations are gone, and even though the name may have 
 remained the same, the substance has changed: a steel- 
 worker to-day is not the same as a steel- worker thirty years 
 ago. 2 A comparison of average wages or earnings for two 
 different periods may therefore be quite misleading. It is 
 possible for the average to show a decrease, though in 
 reality the wages may have increased. This will be clear 
 from the following example in which all figures are purely 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 410. 
 
 For a discussion of this subject see R. Mayo-Smith: Statistics and 
 Economics, pp. 91-102. (Publications of the American Economic As- 
 sociation, vol. iii., Nos. 4, 5.) 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 293 
 
 arbitrary. Suppose, the working force of a mill in 1882 
 consisted of 1000 men, of whom 750 were skilled mechanics 
 whose wages averaged $3.50 a day, and 250 were unskilled 
 laborers hired at $1.25 a day. The average wage for all 
 mill workers was, accordingly, $3.00 per day. Suppose, 
 further, that in the thirty years that have elapsed since, 
 the business of the mill has grown and two new departments 
 have been added, with 1000 men in each. But owing to the 
 installation of new machinery the same 750 skilled me- 
 chanics have been distributed over the three plants, and the 
 additional force of 2000 men consists solely of unskilled labor- 
 ers. Suppose, the wages of the skilled mechanics have been 
 raised from $3.50 to an average of $5.00 per day, and the 
 wages of unskilled laborers from $1.25 to an average of 
 $2.00 per day. The average for the three plants, however, 
 would be $2.75 per day, i. e., twenty-five cents less than 
 thirty years ago, notwithstanding the substantial gain in 
 the wages of all employees. The same defect is inherent 
 in the latest refinements of the average, the "median," 
 the "quartile," the "decile," etc. 
 
 Moreover, our wage statistics present a huge mass of 
 fragmentary and heterogeneous data, which in their present 
 undigested form "are well-nigh inaccessible." 1 The use 
 
 1 Hearing : Wages in the United States, p. 7. The defects of our 
 wage statistics are well stated by Professor Nearing in the following 
 paragraphs: 
 
 "At every turn the need arose for an accurate, concise statement of 
 the wages being paid in the various parts of the United States, yet to 
 date no study has been made which supplies the need. Ryan's Esti- 
 mate is old, and at best incomplete; Mrs. Moore's statement, like the 
 statement in the 1903 Report of the Commissioner of Labor, is of 
 standards of living primarily, and only incidentally of wages. In 
 neither case is the ground covered sufficiently to warrant valuable wage 
 deductions. The Wage Study accompanying the Census of 1900 is old, 
 and rather inadequate, as the compilers themselves point out. . . . 
 The available data on the subject of wages exist chiefly in the reports of 
 State bureaus of labor, and are unfortunately of such a nature as to 
 render comparison with data of a decade since (in the few cases where 
 such data exist) most unsatisfactory. . . . New York wage statistics 
 
294 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of wage statistics, such as they are, for an analysis of the 
 effects of immigration on wages is restricted by lack of 
 comparable statistics of occupations by nativity. 1 
 
 On the other hand, a rise or a fall in money wages is no 
 indication of an increase or decrease of the resources of the 
 wage-earners, unless coupled with comparative statistics 
 of the cost of living. The various index numbers of prices^ 
 however, admit of a wide margin of error. An illustration 
 is furnished by the curve plotted by Mr. Streightoff from 
 the figures of the United States Bureau of Labor on "real 
 wages." 2 It appears that during the period from 1890 to 
 1907, the purchasing power of full-time weekly wages was 
 at its maximum in 1896, when, according to the statistics 
 of the Massachusetts Bureau, the ratio of unemployment 
 was as high as during the crisis year I9o8; 3 the country had 
 
 relate to members of labor unions only; the average wage statistics of 
 Pennsylvania are incomplete even those cited are wretchedly compiled 
 and presented; Illinois has published no recent statement of wages 
 except in department stores; Missouri, Michigan, and Indiana publish 
 little or no wage data. The statistics for Ohio are excellent, but very 
 diffuse and unconcentrated. . . . Therefore, of the ten leading indus- 
 trial States, three present worthy wage data; the statistics of two are 
 far from satisfactory; while five of the ten States furnish no current wage 
 material of value to this study. Deplorable as is the lack of statistics 
 in these great industrial States, the conditions in the country at large 
 are infinitely worse. Of the forty-seven States of the Union, not more 
 than five publish up-to-date wage statistics. Of the remaining States, 
 a score publish statistics of average wages only, which, in some cases, are 
 so unrepresentative as to be valueless. ' ' (Pp. 9-15.) 
 
 "The last Bulletin of the Federal Bureau of Labor relating to wages 
 was published in 1908. . . . The material as a whole permits of 
 practically no deduction, save that wages are considerably higher in the 
 West than in any other section of the country, and that the wages in 
 some trades are very much higher than in others." (Pp. 138-139.) 
 
 * For example, though the average wages of coal miners can be com- 
 puted from census statistics for every State, it is impossible to ascertain 
 for many States the percentage of Slavs among coal miners, because 
 coal miners are combined in census statistics with metalliferous miners 
 and quarrymen. 
 
 2 Streightoff, loc. cit., Chart XI. 
 
 See Ch. VI., Table 23 and Diagram IX. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 295 
 
 not recovered from the effects of the crisis of 1893-1894, and 
 the industrial situation was again disturbed by the uncer- 
 tainty of a Presidential campaign fought on one of the most 
 vital economic issues, the money question. No trust can 
 be placed in statistics which lead to conclusions so glaringly 
 at variance with facts still fresh in people's memory. 
 
 Overlooking, however, the inadequacy of our wage 
 statistics, let us examine the material, such as it is, bearing 
 upon the relation between immigration and wages. 
 
 We have seen that in the 40*3 the wages of Irish street 
 laborers in Brooklyn were insufficient to provide for rent, 
 and they were compelled to live in shanties. Bad as the 
 housing accommodations of the Italian street laborers may 
 be to-day, they nevertheless earn enough to pay rent, which 
 is indisputable proof of an increase in "real wages." 
 
 A generation later, a statistical inquiry into the earnings 
 of 75,000 wage-earners in the State of Massachusetts led 
 the Bureau of Labor Statistics to the conclusion that "the 
 average earnings of a majority of the skilled laborers in this 
 State do not reach the average cost of the necessities of 
 life, " with the result that "the children of the poor are taken 
 away early from school, and brought into the labor market ; 
 the son to the factory, store, or shop, and the daughter to 
 the life and wages of a factory or cash girl, or of a serving 
 woman. ' ' a Evidently the skilled mechanics forty years ago 
 did not fare better than the wage-earners of our own day. 
 
 In the same report there is a comparison of earnings and 
 expenses in Massachusetts for 1800, 1830, and 1860. It is 
 estimated that in 1800 the master mason alone of all crafts- 
 men earned more than his expenses, whereas master carpen- 
 ters and master painters could not pay their expenses; 
 journeymen carpenters, masons, and painters were in the 
 same category. In 1 830 a journeyman mason earned barely 
 
 1 New York Weekly Tribune, May 2, 1846. Quoted in Documentary 
 History of American Industrial Society, vol. viii., pp. 225-226. 
 
 a Third Annual Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of 
 Labor (1871-1872), pp. 531-532- 
 
296 Immigration and Labor 
 
 enough to support a family of four, but the earnings of a 
 journeyman carpenter were still insufficient to provide for a 
 family of the same size. The wages of a laborer were esti- 
 mated at $226 a year, which was equivalent to a little over 
 one half of the estimated expenses of an average family of 
 four persons. In 1860 neither a master carpenter, nor a 
 master painter earned enough to support a family; no 
 journeyman in the building trades was able to support a 
 family solely on his own earnings. The earnings of a common 
 laborer remained, as thirty years before, at a little over one 
 half of the estimated cost of supporting a family. 1 
 
 The Bureau of Statistics of New Jersey in its early days 
 published a number of workmen's budgets. A compilation of 
 the data for 1885 will be found in the Appendix, Tables XIX. 
 and XX. The workmen were either native, or immigrants 
 from Northern and Western Europe. Immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe was still too insignificant to 
 affect the labor situation. It appears that of all wage-earn- 
 ers in specified occupations only glass-workers and black- 
 smiths earned enough to support on their wages an average 
 family of about five persons. Other skilled mechanics, such as 
 machinists and carpenters, needed the assistance of mem- 
 bers of their households to support a family of the same 
 size, while workers in textile mills could not meet expenses 
 even with the assistance of members of their families. 
 Among unskilled laborers there were some whose earnings 
 were sufficient to support their families, but their expenses 
 averaged only $i a day. Those families whose expenses 
 averaged about $1.50 a day or more were barely able to 
 keep above water with the aid of the children's earnings. 
 None of the Irish laborers could make both ends meet, 
 although their expenses were somewhat below those of the 
 other English-speaking laborers. 
 
 There are similar budget data in the report of the Ohio 
 Bureau of Labor Statistics for 1885. In a few trades, the 
 
 1 Third Annual Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of 
 Labor, (1871-1872), pp. 514-517. See Appendix, Table XVIII. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 297 
 
 average earnings were insufficient to provide for the support 
 of the wage-earner and his family. The average deficit per 
 family for each occupation is shown in Table 87 : 
 
 TABLE 87. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL DEFICIT PER WORKING FAMILY IN OHIO, BY OCCU- 
 PATIONS, 1885.* 
 
 Occupation 
 
 Persons in family 
 
 Annual deficit 
 
 Stone-cutters 
 
 5.O 
 
 $ 2 
 
 Machinists 
 
 42 
 
 
 
 4 5 
 
 _5 
 
 Iron-workers 
 
 5.7 
 
 66 
 
 Wood -carvers 
 
 5-6 
 
 lit 
 
 Cigar-makers 
 
 4.8 
 
 114 
 
 Miners 
 
 5-8 
 
 IIQ 
 
 
 
 
 Among the skilled mechanics the stone-cutters and the 
 machinists were on the border line between surplus and de- 
 ficit; the cabinet-makers, wood-carvers and cigar-makers 
 depended upon outside sources, in addition to their wages ; 
 likewise the iron-workers and the miners. The proportion 
 of immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe in those 
 occupations five years later varied in Ohio between 2.1 and 
 5.3 per cent. 
 
 One fact may be taken as firmly established by the pre- 
 ceding statistics, fragmentary and insufficient as they are for 
 other purposes, viz., that in the days of "the old immi- 
 gration*' the wages of unskilled laborers, and even of some 
 of the skilled mechanics, did not fully provide for the support 
 of the wage-earner and his family in accordance with their 
 usual standards of living. The shortage had to be made up 
 by the wife and children. 
 
 If the tendency of the new immigration be to lower the 
 rate of wages or to retard the advance of wages, it should 
 be expected that wages would be lower in great cities where 
 the recent immigrants are concentrated, than in rural dis- 
 tricts where the population is mostly of native birth. All 
 
 ' See Appendix, Table XXI.; 
 
2Q8 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 wage statistics concur, however, in the opposite conclusion. 
 Though the census reports have since 1900 repeatedly 
 warned against the use of census returns for the computation 
 of average earnings, yet the defects of the census statistics 
 of wages do not preclude a fair comparison between the 
 earnings of urban and rural factory operatives. The 
 average number of wage-earners in either case has been 
 computed on a uniform basis of 300 working days per wage- 
 earner. While individual returns may be mere estimates of 
 questionable accuracy, yet these defects are insufficient to 
 obscure a pronounced tendency, such as shown in Table 88. 
 
 TABLE 88. 
 
 AVERAGE EARNINGS OF FACTORY WORKERS, FOR A YEAR OF 30O WORKING 
 
 DAYS, 1904.' 
 
 Location 
 
 Men 
 
 Women 
 
 ChUdren 
 
 Urban 
 Rural 
 
 $566 
 479 
 
 $307 
 264 
 
 $186 
 158 
 
 An examination of previous census reports on manufac- 
 tures as far back as 1870 proves that since the United States 
 has become a manufacturing country average earnings per 
 worker have been higher in the cities than in the country. 2 
 The effect of this difference is "that the country competi- 
 tion of native Americans where the cost of living is low often 
 acts as a depressing effect on wages in the same occupation 
 in cities. ' ' 3 Prof. Commons gives the following explanation 
 
 1 Computed from the Report of the Census of Manufactures, 1905, 
 Part I., United States by Industries, Table I., p. xxxv. 
 
 2 See XII. Census Reports. Manufactures, Part I., pp. ccxx., ccxxi., 
 Tables IV.-VI. ; p. cclix., Tables XXVII. and XXVIII. This difference 
 might be accounted for in part by the employment of relatively greater 
 numbers of women and children in smaller cities and rural settlements. 
 The effect upon the wage situation, however, is the same, whether the 
 better paid workman of the city is underbid by a man, woman, or child 
 employed in a country town. 
 
 3 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. xxiv. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 299 
 
 of "the pressure to reduce wages" which "proceeds from 
 the cheaper labor of country districts employed in the same 
 line of production'*: 
 
 Wages are necessarily higher in cities than in the country for the 
 corresponding standard of living. In the city there are such additional 
 demands as car fare, the food costs more and must be paid for in cash, 
 because the laborer does not have his patch of ground from which, by 
 the help of wife and children and by his own extra work mornings and 
 evenings and idle days, he can secure a large share of his necessary food 
 supplies. 1 
 
 In other words, the American wage-earner in a country 
 district gives more of his time to making a living than the 
 city worker. 
 
 The same difference exists within the same trades between 
 the large cities and the smaller cities. The Industrial 
 Commission, in its volume on immigration, quotes the 
 following from the reports of the New York Bureau of 
 Labor: 
 
 Wages at the present time (in 1898) are good throughout the large 
 cities, where it must be barne in mind the men employed in the building 
 trades have themselves ueen immigrants. In the smaller cities, where 
 the wages are much less than in the larger cities, it is the older American 
 labor which controls the field. 3 
 
 Another way to trace the connection, if any, between 
 immigration and wages, is to compare the average earnings 
 by States with reference to the percentage of foreign-born ; 
 if immigration tends to depress wages, this tendency will 
 manifest itself in lower average earnings for States with a 
 large immigrant population, and vice versa. No such tend- 
 ency is disclosed by wage statistics. In Tables 89 and 90 
 the average earnings of male and female wage- workers above 
 the age of sixteen in the principal manufacturing States are 
 collated with the percentages of all foreign-born and of 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans of the same sex engaged 
 in manufactures and mechanical pursuits. Southern States 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 316. 
 * Ibid ., p. 426. 
 
300 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 where the negroes constitute more than 10 per cent of all 
 persons of both sexes engaged in manufactures have been 
 excluded from this table, in order to eliminate the influence 
 of negro competition upon the average earnings. x 
 
 TABLE 89. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS OF MALE EMPLOYEES IN MANUFACTURES, 
 COLLATED WITH THE PERCENTAGES OF FOREIGN-BORN, IN 
 THE PRINCIPAL STATES, IQOO. 
 
 
 Average annual 
 
 Per cent of all ma 
 
 and mechar 
 
 les in manufactures 
 deal pursuits 
 
 State 
 
 earnings 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans 
 
 Colorado 
 
 $ 630 
 
 38 "i 
 
 IO O 
 
 California 
 
 589 
 
 -14.4. 
 
 4 5 
 
 Washington 
 
 578 
 
 14. Q 
 
 3-1 
 
 New York 
 
 558 
 
 44 O 
 
 o 
 
 TC 4. 
 
 New Mexico 
 
 1 
 
 27 O 
 
 6 8 
 
 Connecticut 
 
 S^O 
 
 f 'j? 
 
 41.6 
 
 8 6 
 
 Illinois 
 
 C-IQ 
 
 4.4. 7 
 
 8 7 
 
 Massachusetts . . 
 
 527 
 
 ** / 
 
 xfiA-i 
 
 4 8 
 
 New Jersey 
 
 CIQ 
 
 Hi 
 
 94. 
 
 Oregon 
 
 5l8 
 
 28.8 
 
 2 I 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 KH 
 
 i-i 2 
 
 T-5 4. 
 
 Nebraska. . 
 
 cio 
 
 *O 7 
 
 30 
 
 Kansas 
 
 4QC 
 
 IO 1 
 
 30 
 
 Rhode Island 
 
 4.8 5 
 
 47. 
 
 5.1 
 
 Delaware 
 
 4.71 
 
 17 7 
 
 4 A 
 
 Texas 
 
 AAX 
 
 */ / 
 
 18 Q 
 
 2 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 No definite relation between wages and immigration can 
 be deduced from the preceding tables. States with widely 
 differing percentages of foreign-born male operatives have 
 the same average earnings, e. g., Illinois, Connecticut, and 
 New Mexico, while States with the same percentages of 
 foreign-born male wage-earners widely differ with respect 
 to rates of wages, e. g. , Colorado and New Jersey. Higher 
 
 *XII. Census. Manufactures, Part I., p. cxv., Table XXXIX.; 
 Population, Part I., pp. cii.-civ., Table XLVL; p. cvi., Table XLVIII., 
 also p. cxiv., Table LIIL 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 301 
 
 percentages of foreign-born go together with higher average 
 earnings, e. #., Rhode Island has more than twice as many 
 foreign-born in proportion as Texas, and the rate of wages 
 in Rhode Island is higher than in Texas. And, on the con- 
 
 TABLE 90. 
 
 AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS OF FEMALE EMPLOYEES IN MANUFACTURES, 
 COLLATED WITH THE PERCENTAGES OF FOREIGN-BORN, IN 
 THE PRINCIPAL STATES, IQOO. 
 
 State 
 
 Average annual 
 earnings 
 
 Percentage of all foreign-born 
 females in manufactures and 
 mechanical pursuits 
 
 Colorado . 
 
 $ W 
 
 Id O 
 
 Massachusetts .... 
 
 -IIQ 
 
 do 6 
 
 Washington 
 
 o'-y 
 Il6 
 
 10 o 
 
 Rhode Island . . 
 
 1O4 
 
 IQ C 
 
 C onn ect ic u t 
 
 102 
 
 27 O 
 
 New York 
 
 o^-* 
 208 
 
 2Q 6 
 
 Illinois . ... 
 
 288 
 
 26 I 
 
 California 
 
 27Q 
 
 17 O 
 
 New Jersey 
 
 '9 
 
 276 
 
 25 1 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 262 
 
 11 O 
 
 Nebraska 
 
 258 
 
 15.8 
 
 New Mexico . 
 
 2^5 
 
 30 
 
 Texas 
 
 251 
 
 IO d 
 
 Oregon 
 
 24.Q 
 
 12.1 
 
 
 215 
 
 6.6 
 
 Delaware 
 
 211 
 
 6.7 
 
 
 
 
 trary, lower percentages of foreign-born go together with 
 higher average wages, e. g. t Kansas and Rhode Island. 
 Neither does immigration from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe appear to affect the average earnings. New York 
 with the highest percentage of immigrants from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe has a higher average than Oregon 
 with the lowest percentage of immigrants from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe. The average earnings of women 
 likewise bear no definite relation to the per cent of foreign- 
 born breadwinners. In Massachusetts, which has the 
 maximum per cent (40.6) of foreign-born breadwinners in 
 
302 Immigration and Labor 
 
 manufacturing and mechanical pursuits, the average earn- 
 ings are $319, whereas in New Mexico, which has the mini- 
 mum per cent of foreign-born breadwinners (3.9), the 
 average earnings are $255. The lowest average earnings, 
 $211 annually, are found in Delaware, with 6.7 per cent of 
 foreign-born women employed in manufactures, while in 
 Massachusetts, with six times as many foreign-born, the 
 average annual earnings were 52 per cent above the Dela- 
 ware average. The preponderance of evidence, to use a 
 legal term, supports the conclusion that, as a rule, the 
 annual earnings are higher in States with a higher percentage 
 of foreign-born factory workers. But making allowance 
 for the few exceptions to this rule, the least that can be 
 said is that there is no proof of a tendency of immigration, 
 old or new, to depress the rate of wages. 
 
 The preceding conclusions based upon an examination of 
 census statistics of average earnings are corroborated by the 
 results of Prof. Nearing's study of wage statistics published 
 by State labor bureaus. He finds " that average wages are 
 rather constant for a given industry from State to State, and 
 from city to city within a State." 1 As the percentage of 
 immigrants among the wage-earners employed in each in- 
 dustry greatly varies from State to State and from city to 
 city, it is evident that immigration does not affect the rate 
 of wages. 
 
 "The opportunities for the new hands depend upon the 
 expansion of industry and the resources of the country," 
 says Professor Commons. ' ' Provided this expansion occurs, 
 there is no overcrowding of the labor market. The new 
 resources and new investments demand new labor; and, 
 if the expansion is strong enough, the new labor as well as 
 the existing labor may secure advances in wages." * 
 
 It is broadly asserted by Professors Jenks and Lauck that 
 the large supply of Southern and^ Eastern European labor 
 "has seriously retarded the advance of wages in those occu- 
 
 1 Nearing, loc. ciL, pp. 145-146. 
 
 a Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 305. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 303 
 
 pations where such labor could be used to advantage." 
 The case of section hands on the railroads is cited as a spe- 
 cific example: their wages are said to have "varied little 
 during the last fifteen years, although the wages in other 
 lines of industry have advanced materially." 1 This con- 
 clusion is at variance with the statistics of the Interstate 
 Commerce Commission, which furnish an accurate record of 
 the yearly fluctuations of average daily wages for the main 
 classes of railway employees. 2 In order to bring out the 
 effect of the supply of Southern and Eastern European labor 
 upon the wages of section hands on the railways, the varia- 
 tions in their wages must be compared with the variations 
 in the wages of other railway employees. It should not 
 be lost sight of that the rates of wages are governed by de- 
 mand, as well as by supply, not by supply alone. That 
 wages in other lines of industry have advanced more rapidly, 
 may have been due to a greater demand for labor in those 
 lines. It is only when the comparison is confined to railway 
 employees that the changes in the rates of wages can be ob- 
 served under uniform conditions. The data for such a com- 
 parison are presented in graphic form in Diagram XVIII. 
 Of the eight classes shown on the diagram all but the lowest 
 two consist of English-speaking employees, while the two 
 lowest grades are filled very largely by immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. The engineers, conductors, 
 and firemen have strong organizations, while the laborers 
 and trackmen are unorganized. The raises secured by the 
 latter have come solely through the operation of the law of 
 supply and demand. The wage curves for all classes but 
 general office clerks show a rising tendency; the variations 
 from year to year are almost parallel. The office clerks are 
 the only class whose wages have remained practically sta- 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 206-207. In a preceding paragraph 
 this specific example is qualified by the statement that "in certain cases 
 they [immigrants hired for railroad section work] have been paid even 
 more than the laborers previously employed, the latter being insufficient 
 in number to meet the increasing demand. " (p. 206). 
 
 2 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, Table 169, p. 266. 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 tionary; considering the increased cost of living, their real 
 wages have in fact declined. The clerical force is, with few 
 exceptions, either of native or of Northern and Western 
 European birth. Thus while the wages of Southern and 
 Eastern European section hands have been raised to meet 
 
 DIAGRAM XVIII. 
 
 *4 
 
 *Z- 
 
 a 
 
 I S I 
 
 TXACfMCM 
 
 <WUCTO*' mym .. 
 
 LA**C*9 
 
 * I 
 
 J " 
 
 XVIIL Average daily wages of railroad employees, 1891-1909. 
 
 the increased cost of living, the salary of the American office 
 clerk has not been advanced. 
 
 The Immigration Commission seeks to hold immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe responsible even for the 
 low pay of clerical help: 
 
 "There is the general feeling that in so far as the recent 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 305 
 
 immigrants are entering occupations in which Americans are 
 engaged, they are rendering those occupations undesirable. 
 The American laborer does not care in many cases to work 
 with the 'Hunkie/ and he resents the latter's presence and 
 in many cases transfers his own labor to an occupation such 
 as a clerkship at lower wages. " z 
 
 Thus because the American street laborer deems it 
 beneath his station in life to work side by side with a 
 "Hunkie," he is said to be willing to accept at a sacri- 
 fice a more respectable position at a desk in a railway 
 or mining office. The Commission has produced no 
 statistics to show the percentage of clerical employees 
 with a previous experience as section hands and mine 
 laborers. On the other hand, preference for clerical work 
 among the children of American mechanics antedates 
 the advent of the "Hunkie." A discussion of the subject 
 is found in a report of the Illinois Bureau of Labor as far 
 back as 1 886. First among the reasons ' ' why the American- 
 bred youth seek clerkships" is noted "the distaste of the 
 American youth for the trades. " 3 Obviously, the Slav and 
 Italian laborers ought not to be burdened with responsi- 
 bility for the oversupply of native American labor in clerical 
 pursuits. 
 
 No evidence of the alleged tendency of Southern and 
 Eastern European labor to retard the advance of wages can 
 be found in the two basic industries which are generally 
 regarded as representative of the conditions produced by 
 recent immigration the coal and the iron and steel in- 
 dustry. In the latter, the Immigration Commission finds, 
 "the extensive employment of recent immigrants has been 
 attended by an increase in rates of wages due to the general 
 scarcity of labor in the face of the remarkable industrial 
 expansion of recent years." 3 This statement should be 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 583. 
 3 Fourth Annual Report of the Bureau of Statistics of Labor of the 
 State of Illinois, p. 227. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 440. 
 
3o6 Immigration and Labor 
 
 supplemented by the fact, brought to light by the Pitts- 
 burgh Survey, that while the wages of the Southern and 
 Eastern European laborers in the steel mills have increased, 
 the wages of the semi-skilled and skilled men mostly 
 Americans or old immigrants of the English-speaking races 
 have remained stationary, which is in effect equivalent to 
 a lowering of the standard of wages ; and the money wages of 
 the labor aristocracy, none of whom are Southern and East- 
 ern Europeans, have been actually reduced. 1 The same 
 tendency is observed in the unionized coal mines of the 
 Pittsburgh district: the wages of the unskilled men are 
 much higher than those paid for the same grade of labor in 
 the steel mills, whereas the wages of the skilled men are the 
 same in the mills and mines for work of the same class. In 
 the coal mines, as in the steel mills, unskilled work is done 
 almost exclusively by Southern and Eastern Europeans, 
 while the skilled men are mostly of the "English-speaking" 
 races. 3 
 
 To be sure, there is a continuous readjustment of wages 
 to prices. The employer of labor seeks to recoup the ad- 
 vance in wages, by advancing the price of his product to the 
 consumer. When the advance in the price of manufactured 
 products becomes general, the wage-earner, as a consumer, 
 is forced in effect to give up a part or all of his gain in the 
 money rate of wages. The increased cost of living then 
 stimulates further demands for advances in wages. Since 
 combinations of capital in all fields of industry have reduced 
 competition among employers of labor to a minimum, the 
 wage-earners have been at a disadvantage in this con- 
 tinuous bargaining. The Immigration Commission holds 
 that the bargaining power of labor has been impaired by 
 ''the availability of the large supply of recent immigrant 
 labor," which "has undoubtedly had the effect of prevent- 
 ing an increase of wages to the extent which would have 
 
 1 This subject is specially treated further, in Chapter XX., on the 
 Steel-Workers. 
 
 1 See Chapter XXL, on the Coal Miners. 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages 307 
 
 been necessary had the expansion in the local industries oc- 
 curred without the availability of the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans." 1 
 
 Instead of conjecturing what "would have resulted . . . 
 from the increased demand for labor," 2 under imaginary 
 conditions, it is safer to inquire what were the actual effects 
 of business prosperity on wages in past American history 
 ''without the availability of the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans." A fair basis for comparison is offered by the 
 Civil War period. "With the exception of the first year, 
 the Civil War period was one of prosperity in manufactures, 
 transportation, mining, and agriculture. Profits were large 
 . . . New woolen factories were opened; many were 
 operated day and night. Dividends of ten to twenty 
 per cent were common; and larger returns were not un- 
 known." 3 On the other hand, the cost of living rose 
 as rapidly as in recent years; though the causes were 
 different, the effect upon the wage-earner's budget was the 
 same. The wage-earners were apparently in a favorable 
 situation: "The war caused an unprecedented drain of 
 workers from the productive industries into the army," 4 
 whereas immigration dropped during the first two years. s 
 The effect of that situation on wages is shown graphically 
 in Diagram XIX., reproduced in part from Chart XII. of 
 
 1 Reports, vol. 8, p. 440. The sentence is self -contradictory in form, 
 presuming to state "the effect" which a hypothetical condition 
 "has undoubtedly had", although, as a matter of fact, the combina- 
 tion of causes which "would have" made the effect "necessary" never 
 occurred. This idea is not original with the Immigration Commis- 
 sion. It is referred to in the following terms by Prof. Commons in 
 his report on immigration: "It is possible, of course, that the presence 
 of immigrants in large numbers may prevent wages from reaching as 
 high a level in time of prosperity as they otherwise would reach, but 
 this cannot, in the nature of the case, be demonstrated." Reports of the 
 Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 309. 
 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 540-541. 
 
 * Frank Tracy Carlton: The History and Problems of Organized 
 Labor, pp. 52-53. . Ibid., p. 51. 
 
 5 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , pp. 79-80. 
 
308 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 DIAGRAM XIX. 
 
 To 
 
 60 
 
 1861 
 
 63 
 
 '64- 
 
 XIX. Medians of relative cost 
 
 of living and average of 
 
 biennial medians of 
 
 relative wages, 
 
 1861-1865. 
 
 Prof. Wesley C. Mitchell's 
 painstaking study of "Gold, 
 Prices, and Wages under the 
 Greenback Standard." The 
 cost of living rose more rap- 
 idly than money wages. In 
 other words, "without the 
 availability of Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans," real 
 wages decreased. 1 
 
 It must be noted that "af- 
 ter 1862 labor agitation be- 
 came considerable. . . . Until 
 near the end of the war 
 strikes were usually successful ; 
 but they were not sufficiently 
 successful to cause theincrease 
 in wages to keep pace with 
 rising prices. " 2 This compar- 
 ison shows that the hypoth- 
 esis of the Immigration Com- 
 mission concerning the extent 
 of the increase of wages 
 "which would have been nec- 
 essary had the expansion of 
 American industries occurred 
 without the availability of the 
 
 1 The decrease in real wages dur- 
 ing the period of the Civil War, 
 according to the Aldrich Report, 
 was as follows (Carlton, loc t cit., p. 
 55): 
 
 Year Per cent 
 
 1861 
 
 1862 
 
 "- I86 3 
 I86 4 
 1865 
 a Ibid., pp. 57-58. 
 
 100 
 87 
 74 
 66 
 66 
 
Effect of Immigration on Wages - 309 
 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans," does not fit the facts of 
 American economic history. 
 
 The facts brought to light by the investigations of the 
 Immigration Commission furnish ground for the assump- 
 tion paradoxical as it may seem at a superficial glance 
 that the availability of the large supply of recent immigrant 
 labor has prevented a reduction of the wages of the older 
 employees. 
 
 The prime force which has made industrial expansion so 
 rapid in recent times has been the general introduction of 
 labor-saving machinery. The immediate effect of the intro- 
 duction of every new machine has been the displacement of 
 the trained mechanic by the unskilled laborer. To be sure, 
 the cheapness of machine-made products stimulates con- 
 sumption of manufactured goods and creates an increased 
 demand for labor, which in the long run offsets the loss of 
 employment caused by the introduction of machinery. 
 But this is true only on the assumption of a considerable 
 industrial expansion. To use bituminous coal mining 
 as an example: in the mines of West Virginia a team of 
 two skilled pick-miners can produce 10 tons of coal a day; 
 but, where machine mining has been introduced, one ma- 
 chine runner with one helper and eight loaders can turn out 
 50 tons a day. * Accordingly, if a force of 100 skilled pick- 
 miners produced 500 tons of coal per day, the same output 
 would be produced with the aid of machinery by a force of 
 20 skilled machine men and 80 laborers. It may be assumed 
 that the requisite number of common laborers would be 
 found in the home market. In order to provide skilled work 
 for the 80 pick-miners displaced by the machine, the daily 
 output of coal must be increased to 2500 tons, which would 
 require an additional supply of 320 unskilled laborers. 
 Suppose, through restriction of immigration, the additional 
 supply of unskilled labor were cut down one half. The total 
 available supply of labor would then consist of the 20 pick- 
 
 1 Annual Report of the Department of Mines, West Virginia (1909), 
 PP- xi., 73, 152. 153- 
 
310 Immigration and Labor 
 
 miners who might find employment as machine runners and 
 helpers, the 80 laborers who would displace an equal num- 
 ber of pick-miners, the 80 pick-miners displaced by the 
 machine, and an additional supply of 160 unskilled immi- 
 grant laborers, in all 340 men. The force of operatives could 
 then be increased only to 34 teams, consisting of 68 skilled 
 miners and 272 laborers; there would be only 48 vacancies 
 of a higher grade for the 80 skilled miners displaced by 
 machinery; and the remaining 32 would have to accept 
 employment at loading coal of course at the usual wages 
 paid for common labor. The fact noted by the Immigration 
 Commission, that only "a small part " of the old employees, 
 consisting of the inefficient element, are in competition with 
 the recent immigrants, is of course the "result of the ex- 
 pansion of the industry," which has opened to "the larger 
 proportion" opportunities for "advancement to the more 
 skilled and responsible positions." 1 These opportunities, 
 however, were conditional upon the availability of a pro- 
 portionate supply of immigrant labor for unskilled and 
 subordinate positions. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, voL I, p. 236. 
 
CHAPTER XIII 
 
 HOURS OF LABOR 
 
 EVERY reduction of the hours of labor, even when not 
 accompanied by an increase of the daily or weekly 
 wage, is equivalent to an increase of the hourly wage. More- 
 over, a reduction in the day's work, all other things being 
 equal, provides more days of work for every employee, 
 which brings a direct increase of earnings. The length of 
 the working day accordingly offers a fair measure of the 
 effects of immigration on labor conditions. It is not com- 
 plicated by the variations of the purchasing power of 
 money, nor is it affected by the uncertainties of the index 
 numbers. A reduction of hours is an unerring arithmetical 
 fact. And, fortunately, the publications of the Federal 
 and State labor bureaus furnish ample material for a com- 
 parative study of the hours of labor from the beginnings of 
 the factory system in the United States. 
 
 There is unconscious humor in the first report of the 
 Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics on early factory 
 conditions: 
 
 The earliest operatives in our mills were of the home population an 
 active, intelligent, industrious, thrifty, well-educated, orderly, and 
 cleanly body of young men and women, . . . daughters of independent 
 farmers, educated in our common schools, (for years they supplied a 
 periodical with articles written wholly by themselves,) who could think 
 and act for themselves, who knew right from wrong, fair treatment 
 from oppression, and who would be grateful for the one, and would 
 not submit to the other. 1 
 
 1 Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor, 1869-1870, 
 pp. 91-92. 
 
 3" 
 
312 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Interpolated amid this eulogy of "the American element* 
 is the following matter-of-fact statement: "The system ot 
 long hours was first adopted. . . . The general length 
 of time per day was 14 or 15 hours." Further on it is 
 related that "the customary time" was "from sunrise to 
 sunset, which, in one half of the year, would give from six- 
 teen to twelve hours, and in the other half, from nine hours 
 to twelve." 
 
 The subject is treated more thoroughly in the recent 
 report of the United States Bureau of Labor on "Woman 
 and Child Wage-Earners." 
 
 The hours of labor in textile factories in the early part of the nine- 
 teenth century were much longer than within recent years. In 
 Massachusetts in 1825 the " time of employment " in incorporated manu- 
 facturing companies was "generally 12 or 13 hours each day, excepting 
 the Sabbath. " Of the places which reported the number of hours in 
 that year, at only two, Ludlow and Newbury, were the hours as low as 
 1 1 a day. ... At Duxboro the hours were from sunrise to sunset, and 
 at Troy (Fall River) and Wellington the employees worked "all day." 
 In 1826, 15 or 1 6 hours constituted . . . the working day at Ware, 
 Mass. . . . 
 
 By the thirties the hours appear to have been, if anything, longer. 
 At Fall River, about 1830, the hours were from 5 a.m., or as soon as light, 
 to 7:30 p. m., or till dark in summer, with one half hour for breakfast 
 and the same time for dinner at noon, making a day of 13^ hours. 
 In general the hours of labor in textile factories in New Hampshire, 
 Rhode Island, and Massachusetts in 1832 were said to be 13 a day. But 
 at the Eagle Mill, Griswold, Conn., it was said that 15 hours and 10 
 minutes actual labor in the mill were required. 
 
 At Paterson, N. J., in 1835, the women and children were obliged to be 
 at work at 4:30 in the morning. They were allowed half an hour for 
 breakfast and three-quarters of an hour for dinner, and then worked as 
 long as they could see. ... At Manayunk, Philadelphia, in 1833, the 
 hours of work were said to be 13 a day. And a little later the hours at 
 the Schuylkill factory, Philadelphia, were " from sunrise to sunset, from 
 the 2 1st of March to the 2Oth September, inclusively, and from sunrise 
 until 8 o'clock p. m. during the remainder of the year. " One hour was 
 allowed for dinner and half an hour for breakfast during the first-men- 
 tioned six months, and one hour for dinner during the other half year. 
 On Saturdays the mill was stopped "one hour before sunset for the pur- 
 pose of cleaning the machinery. " 
 
Hours of Labor 
 
 Overtime, too, was frequent. Many of the corporations at Lowell . . . 
 ran "a certain quantity of their machinery, certain portions of the year, 
 until 9, and half past 9 o'clock at night, with the same set of hands. ". . . 
 Even the operatives were often against a reduction of hours, believing 
 that it would result in a reduction of wages. Harriet Farley, editor of 
 the Lowell Offering . . . thought it would work hardship to widows who 
 were toiling for their children, to children who were toiling for their 
 parents, and to many others. 1 
 
 Toward the close of the '30*5 Irish immigration began to 
 pour into the mills of Massachusetts. " Under the preju- 
 dice of nationality . . . the American element . . . retired 
 from mill and factory. ' ' a The retirement of the ' ' daughters 
 of independent farmers " and their replacement by Irish im- 
 migrants was followed by a reduction of the hours of labor 
 in the textile mills. In 1872 the working day averaged n 
 hours. 3 A generation before, in 1 835 , it was only after a strike 
 that the native American mill hands at Paterson, N. J., won 
 a reduction of the working day to an average of 1 1 J^ hours. 4 
 
 Later immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 brought new racial elements to the mills and factories of 
 Massachusetts. The effect of the "new immigration" 
 upon hours of labor is shown in Table 91 . 
 
 TABLE 91. 
 
 WEEKLY HOURS OF LABOR IN MASSACHUSETTS, 1872 AND 1903.* 
 
 Industry 
 
 1872 
 
 1903 
 
 Reduction 
 
 Boots and shoes 
 
 n 
 
 e-i 
 
 6 
 
 Cotton goods 
 
 66 
 
 o> 
 
 n 
 
 8 
 
 Woolen goods 
 
 66 
 
 58 
 
 8 
 
 
 
 
 
 * Report of Woman and Child Wage-Earners in United Stofe$,vol.ix.. 
 pp. 62-63, 66. 
 
 Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor ; 1869-1870, 
 pp. 9 1-92. J See Table 9 1 . 
 
 Report of Woman and Child Wage-Earners, vol. ix., p. 63. 
 
 5 Figures computed from Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor 
 Statistics, 1872, pp. 119-217; Nineteenth Annual Report of the Com- 
 missioner of Labor, Table V. 
 
314 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The factory workers of Massachusetts gained during the 
 period of the new immigration an average reduction of 7.3 
 hours a week, or about an hour and a quarter per day. In 
 the woolen mills the gain in time was even slightly above the 
 average, although forty years ago the mill operatives were 
 mostly Irish immigrants, whereas lately the mills have been 
 run with a polyglot help made up of all the races of Southern 
 and Eastern Europe and Asiatic Turkey (as has been 
 brought to public attention by the recent strike at Law- 
 rence) . The conditions in the textile mills of Massachusetts 
 are certainly far from ideal; nevertheless fifty-eight hours 
 a week are a great stride in advance since the period when 
 the customary time was from sunrise to sunset, "as long as 
 they could see. " And it cannot be "said that all improve- 
 ments in conditions" of the textile workers "have been 
 secured in spite of the presence of the recent immigrant," 1 
 because there was no one else to secure those improvements 
 for them. 
 
 Taking the United States as a whole, we find that since 
 the beginning of the "new immigration" the hours of labor 
 have been gradually reduced; "the decrease in the hours of 
 labor in 1907, as compared with 1890, was 5.7 per cent." 2 
 This fact shows at least that the recent immigrant has not 
 hindered the movement toward better conditions of employ- 
 ment. It would require some proof to sustain the contention 
 of the Immigration Commission that "his availability and 
 his general characteristics and attitude have constituted a 
 passive opposition which has been most effective." 3 
 
 The Commission has made no investigation on the sub- 
 ject of hours of labor, except in a casual way. There is a 
 table giving the hours of work in one unnamed steel concern. 
 It appears that in the blast furnace department all hands, 
 skilled and unskilled alike, work twelve hours. In all other 
 departments the unskilled laborers work ten hours, whereas 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , p. 541 
 
 2 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 77, p. 4. 
 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 541. 
 
Hours of Labor 315 
 
 the hours of the skilled and semi-skilled employees vary as 
 follows: in 7 occupations, 8 hours; in 143 occupations, 10 
 hours; in 269 occupations, 12 hours. In the coal mines 
 operated by the same concern, the laborers work 10 hours, 
 whereas the skilled and semi-skilled employees in 34 out of 
 42 occupations work 12 hours, and only in 8 occupations 
 10 hours. 1 The unskilled laborers in the mines and mills 
 are mostly recent immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, whereas the skilled and semi-skilled positions are 
 filled almost exclusively by native Americans and old Eng- 
 lish-speaking immigrants. The Immigration Commission 
 itself says that "the immigrant does not appear . . . at the 
 present time to be even competing with him [the American] 
 in any serious way for the better-paid positions." 2 It is 
 evident that the longer hours of the English-speaking em- 
 ployees are not the result of recent immigration, since the 
 recent immigrants themselves work shorter hours. 
 
 The report on the cotton industry shows that in 1845 
 the working day in the cotton mills averaged 12 hours 
 and 10 minutes; the shortest days were in December and 
 January, averaging 1 1 hours and 24 minutes, and the long- 
 est in April were as high as 13 hours and 31 minutes. At 
 the time the report was written, the working hours were 56 
 per week, i. e., 10 hours per day with a half holiday on Satur- 
 day. 3 Thus sixty years of immigration have been attended 
 by a reduction of 2 hours and 50 minutes in the length of the 
 working day in the cotton mills. 
 
 The most complete statistics of hours of labor are con- 
 tained in the reports of the factory inspectors of the State 
 of New York, covering an average of nearly a million factory 
 employees annually , f or 1 90 1 - 1 9 1 o . New York is affected 
 by immigration more than any other State in the Union. 
 The period under consideration has witnessed the greatest 
 volume of immigration known in the history of the United 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, Table 281, pp. 377- 
 381. a Ibid., vol. 8, p. 583. 
 
 J Ibid., vol. n, pp. 273 and 290. 
 
3i6 Immigration and Labor 
 
 > 
 
 States, and the bulk of that immigration has been from the 
 countries of Southern and Eastern Europe. The reports on 
 factory inspection in the State of New York, therefore, offer 
 the results of observation, under conditions best calculated 
 to bring out the effects of immigration. Moreover, the 
 figures for the city of New York can be compared with those 
 for the rest of the State. In the city of New York the 
 foreign-born population furnished in 1900, 50.7 per cent of 
 all persons engaged in manufactures and mechanical pur- 
 suits, while in the State outside of New York the ratio was 
 only 22.9 per cent. The natives of Southern and Eastern 
 Europe constituted in the same year 16.1 per cent of the 
 total population of New York City, and 2.1 per cent of the 
 total population of the State outside of New York City. By 
 1910 their proportion in New York City increased to 
 24.1 per cent and in the remainder of the State to 6.6 per 
 cent. 1 
 
 The per cent distribution of factory operatives by the 
 number of hours of work in and outside of New York City 
 is given in Table 92 on the next page. The figures show: 
 
 (1) That the decade of the heaviest immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe was marked by a gradual 
 reduction of the hours of labor in the State of New York; 
 
 (2) That the percentage of factory operatives working 
 ten hours or less on week days with a half -holiday on Satur- 
 day was much greater in New York City with its large 
 colonies of alien workers than in the remainder of the State 
 with a working population predominantly native; 
 
 (3) That after a decade of "undesirable immigration" 
 more than two thirds of all factory workers in New York 
 City work ten hours or less on week days with a half holi- 
 day on Saturday, whereas in the remainder of the State the 
 majority still work longer hours. 
 
 The preconceived notions about the "general character- 
 
 1 XIII. Census. Population, vol. i, pp. 79, 148, 825-827, 832 (com- 
 puted). 
 
Hours of Labor 
 
 3*7 
 
 istics" of the recent immigrant do not stand the scrutiny 
 of incontrovertible statistical figures. 
 
 TABLE 92. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF FACTORY OPERATIVES BY WEEKLY HOURS OF 
 LABOR IN NEW YORK CITY AND IN NEW YORK STATE OUTSIDE OF 
 NEW YORK CITY, 
 
 
 New York City 
 
 New York State outside of 
 New York City 
 
 Year 
 
 
 
 
 57 hours or 
 
 58 hours and 
 
 57 hours or 
 
 58 hours and 
 
 
 less 
 
 over 
 
 less 
 
 over 
 
 I9OI 
 
 53-7 
 
 46-3 
 
 I 7 .8 
 
 82.2 
 
 1902 
 
 54-8 
 
 45-2 
 
 22.2 
 
 77-8 
 
 1903 
 
 65.8 
 
 34-2 
 
 25.2 
 
 74-8 
 
 1904 
 1905 
 
 67.4 
 68.8 
 
 32.6 
 31-2 
 
 31-8 
 34-5 
 
 68.2 
 65-5 
 
 1906 
 
 69.0 
 
 31-0 
 
 35-0 
 
 65.0 
 
 1907 
 
 71.2 
 
 28.8 
 
 38.5 
 
 61.5 
 
 1908 
 
 70.9 
 
 29.1 
 
 40.9 
 
 59-1 
 
 1909 
 
 71.5 
 
 28.5 
 
 39-5 
 
 60.5 
 
 I9IO 
 
 75-5 
 
 24-5 
 
 40.4 
 
 59-6 
 
 1 Annual Report of the New York Bureau of Labor, vol. ii., 1910, Table 
 31, p. xlvi. 
 
CHAPTER XIV 
 
 CHILD LABOR 
 
 labor has a depressing effect upon the rate of 
 wages. Thousands of children of immigrants are 
 employed in the mills of New England and the Middle 
 Atlantic States. The inference which readily suggests itself 
 to the popular mind is that child labor is the product of 
 immigration. It is a historical fact, however, that child 
 labor originated in the United States with the introduction of 
 the factory system during the first quarter of the nineteenth 
 century. Early writers on economic subjects favored the 
 employment of children in factories, because it would save 
 adult male labor for agriculture, fishing, shipping, and the 
 skilled trades. Child labor was advocated on religious and 
 philanthropic grounds. The various immigrant races which 
 succeeded one another in the nineteenth century found child 
 labor as an integral part of the factory system in the United 
 States. 1 
 
 During the ten-year period from 1899 to 1909, with its 
 unprecedented immigration, the average number of children 
 employed in factories remained stationary, viz., in 1899- 
 161,276, in 1909162,493, while the relative number de- 
 creased from 3.4 per cent to 2.4 per cent of all wage-earners. 2 
 
 1 Carlton, loc. cit., pp. 380-385. 
 
 1 XIII. Census, vol. viii. Manufactures, p. 253. It is probable that 
 the number of children at work has decreased as well. The number of 
 wage-earners for 1899, owing to the method of computation followed 
 at the XII. Census, was considerably underestimated: The average 
 number was computed "by using 12, the-number of calendar months, 
 as a divisor into the total of the average numbers reported for each 
 month." The effect of this method is shown in the case of twelve 
 
 318 
 
Child Labor 
 
 The most significant fact to be noted concerning the rela- 
 tion between child labor and immigration is the large pro- 
 portion of children employed in factories in States where 
 there is practically no immigrant population. Children of 
 native-born American parents are drawn into the mills as a 
 substitute for immigrant labor. This conclusion is derived 
 from Table 93, showing the dependence of factories upon 
 child labor in six leading manufacturing States, according 
 to the recent census. 
 
 TABLE 93. 
 
 PER CENT OF CHILDREN UNDER 1 6 EMPLOYED IN FACTORIES, IN THE 
 
 UNITED STATES AND IN SIX LEADING MANUFACTURING STATES, 
 
 1909, AND PER CENT OF FOREIGN-BORN, I9IO. 1 
 
 State 
 
 Per cent of children 
 to all wage-earners 
 
 Per cent of foreign- 
 born to total 
 population 
 
 United States 
 
 2.4 
 
 14.7 
 
 
 
 
 South Carolina 
 
 I2.Q 
 
 O 4. 
 
 North Carolina 
 
 II .1 
 
 o.^ 
 
 IVtassachtisetts 
 
 I C 
 
 IJ C 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 *.* 
 
 18.8 
 
 Illinois 
 
 I c 
 
 21 4. 
 
 New York 
 
 0.8 
 
 ^O.2 
 
 
 
 
 In the four leading manufacturing States of the North 
 with a large immigrant population, child labor holds a sub- 
 ordinate place in the industrial organization, while in North 
 and South Carolina one in every eight or nine factory 
 operatives is under the age of 16. The lowest per cent of 
 child workers is in New York, which is overrun by immi- 
 grants, old and new. 
 
 selected industries, where the average number computed "as an abstract 
 unit (like the foot-pound) " was 475,473, whereas the total "computed 
 on the basis of time in operation would have exceeded 650,000, " the 
 variation being as high as 36 per cent. XII. Census. Manufactures, 
 Part I., pp. cvi., ex., and cxi. 
 
 1 XIII. Census, vol. viii.: Manufactures, pp. 270-271; vol. i: Popu- 
 lation, pp. 161-162. 
 
320 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The latest available statistics of the distribution of chil- 
 dren employed in manufactures by nativity relate to the 
 year 1900. The figures are given in Table 94. 
 
 TABLE 94. 
 
 DISTRIBUTION, BY PARENT NATIVITY AND COLOR, OF THE NUMBER OP 
 CHILDREN OF BOTH SEXES, IO TO 15 YEARS OF AGE, ENGAGED IN 
 MANUFACTURES AND MECHANICAL PURSUITS, BY GEOGRAPHICAL 
 DIVISIONS, 
 
 Race and Nativity 
 
 Con- 
 tinental 
 United 
 States 
 
 North 
 Atlantic 
 Division 
 
 North 
 Central 
 Division 
 
 Western 
 Division 
 
 South 
 Atlantic 
 Division 
 
 South 
 Central 
 Division 
 
 Number: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 White: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Native parents 
 
 II4,88l 
 
 46,534 
 
 19.155 
 
 1,696 
 
 35,292 
 
 I2,2O4 
 
 Foreign parents 
 
 159.679 
 
 104,574 
 
 44.796 
 
 3,199 
 
 4,172 
 
 3,038 
 
 Colored 
 
 9.7OQ 
 
 AQT. 
 
 670 
 
 288 
 
 A 78/1 
 
 306 s ? 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 283,860 
 
 151,601 
 
 64.,6'U) 
 
 5,081 
 
 44,248 
 
 18,107 
 
 Per cent: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 White: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Native parents 
 Foreign parents 
 Colored 
 
 40.5 
 56-3 
 5.2 
 
 30.7 
 69.0 
 
 O.^ 
 
 29.6 
 
 69-3 
 I.I 
 
 62.9 
 
 c 7 
 
 79.8 
 
 9-4 
 10 8 
 
 66.7 
 16.6 
 16 7 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 IOO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 In the country at large, the percentage ratio of children 
 of each nativity employed in manufactures corresponded to 
 the percentage of all breadwinners of the same nativity, 
 engaged in manufacturing and mechanical pursuits. 2 In 
 other words, on the whole the foreign-born sent to the 
 factories no more than their quota of children. There is a 
 marked difference, however, in the ratio of children of native 
 parents for each section of the country: in the South the 
 
 1 Occupations, XII. Census, Table LVIIL, p. clix. 
 
 "The per cent distribution, by parent nativity and color, of persons 
 of all ages engaged in manufactures in the United States was as follows: 
 white of native parentage, 39.8 per cent; white of foreign parentage, 
 56.0 per cent; colored, 4.2 per cent. Ibid., Table XXXVI., p. cxiii. 
 
Child Labor 321 
 
 overwhelming majority of factory workers under 16 years 
 of age are children of native parents. 
 
 Another important fact is the age distribution of children 
 employed in factories. The Immigration Commission in its 
 study of households of cotton-mill operatives in the North 
 Atlantic States found but one child under 14 years of age at 
 work in a total of 795 children between 6 and 13 years, and 
 that a French-Canadian. * There are as yet no comparable 
 data more recent than the census figures for 1900. The 
 latter are presented in Table 95. 
 
 TABLE 95. 
 
 COTTON-MILL OPERATIVES UNDER 14 YEARS OP AGE IN THE PRINCIPAL 
 
 MANUFACTURING STATES, IQOO. 8 
 State Number 
 
 New England: 
 
 Maine 602 
 
 New Hampshire 527 
 
 Massachusetts 199 
 
 Connecticut 50 
 
 Rhode Island 615 
 
 Middle Atlantic: \ 
 
 New York 51 
 
 New Jersey 1 16 
 
 Pennsylvania 311 
 
 Southern: j 
 
 North Carolina 5515 
 
 South Carolina 103 
 
 Georgia 2637 
 
 Alabama 1608 
 
 While, as has been shown above, the absolute number of 
 children employed in factories is greater in the North than 
 in the South, the children under 14 in the cotton mills of 
 the South far outnumber those of the same age in the great 
 manufacturing States of the North. This is, no doubt, due 
 to the child-labor laws of the Northern States. 
 
 No one in the Northern States to-day defends the employ- 
 ment of children under 14 in factories. In the Southern 
 States, however, the economic needs of the growing manu- 
 facturing industries have produced eloquent advocates of 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, Table 46, p. 419. 
 a Occupations at the XII. Census, Table LXV., pp. ckix.-clxxxv. 
 
322 Immigration and Labor 
 
 child labor in positions of influence. x Foreign-born wage- 
 earners are a negligible factor in the Southern labor market. 
 The growth of manufacturing industries in the South is 
 restricted by the natural increase of the native population. 
 In order to extend their operations, the manufacturers 
 of the South must resort to the employment of children, as 
 did their predecessors in New England a century ago before 
 immigration came to supply the needs of American industry. 
 
 This situation is by no means confined to the South. 
 Absence of foreign immigration has created a demand for 
 the labor of native American children in the canneries and 
 shoe factories of rural and semi-urban Missouri. 
 
 The rural districts of Missouri lost, from 1900 to 1910, 
 3 . 5 per cent of their population. The total population of the 
 State increased only 6 per cent. The foreign-born in 
 1910, as well as in 1900, constituted 7 per cent of the total 
 population of the State at large, and only ? 3.3 per cent of the 
 State outside of St. Louis and Kansas City. The additions 
 to the foreign-born population through immigration since 
 the census of 1900 averaged only 1310 persons annually, 
 but the increase was concentrated in St. Louis and Kansas 
 City, whereas the remainder of the State lost in ten years 
 8380 of its foreign-born population. 2 The statistics of the 
 State Labor Bureau show an increase of the number of 
 working children in the smaller cities, the towns and rural 
 sections, "which can be traced to the large number of shoe 
 factories and canneries which sprang up, outside of St. Louis, 
 Kansas City, and St. Joseph, during 1908." The foreign- 
 born labor supply in those sections is negligible. The 
 Commissioner of Labor offers the following explanation for 
 the increase in the employment of children: 
 
 1 "The cotton mills are set forth ... as the savior of the people, re- 
 ligiously, educationally, and, according to Dr. Stiles, physically." 
 Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science , 
 Supplement, March, 1910. A. J. McKelwayrThe Mill or the Farm, p. 54. 
 
 2 XIII. Census. Population, vol. i., pp. 27, 61, 135, 149, 178 (com- 
 puted). 
 
Child Labor 323 
 
 The increase in working women and children in 1908 over 1907, shown 
 by these statistics, does not mean that conditions are such that those 
 who ought to remain at home and take care of domestic affairs must go 
 out into the world and toil, but in reality is due to an increase in the 
 number of establishments in which the light, delicate touch of a gentle 
 hand is needed, instead of strength, endurance, and mechanical labor. . . . 
 It is necessary to state here that while the canning industry of Missouri 
 is still in its infancy, the year 1908 was probably the best the State has 
 ever had in this line, and that is why more employees were needed. . . . 
 The increase in child labor was not due to the stringency, the increased 
 cost of living, or to the poorer condition of the masses, but, instead, to 
 an increased demand for these workers from the new canneries and shoe 
 factories. Both these lines have a class of very light work, suitable only 
 for boys and girls, which does not pay enough weekly for older persons. 
 This assertion is not made in defence of child labor, but merely to explain 
 why it exists in canneries and shoe factories. x 
 
 The explanation sounds very similar to that offered in the 
 Southern States. 2 It accounts, as far as it goes, for the em- 
 ployment of children in canneries: an agricultural com- 
 munity is the natural location for the canning industry, 
 outside labor is scarce in rural districts and the canning 
 season is short. No local advantage for the shoe factories, 
 however, exists in rural Missouri. The centre of the shoe 
 manufacturing industry is Massachusetts, which in 1905 
 contributed 45 per cent of the total output of the United 
 States. 3 The seat of the shoe-manufacturing industry of 
 Missouri is St. Louis, whose output increased from 74 per 
 cent of the total for the State in 1899 to 81 per cent in 1904. 4 
 
 1 Reports of the Missouri Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1909, pp. 320-321. 
 
 3 " The cotton mills were the most powerful opponents [of theLouisiana 
 child-labor law], ably seconded by the canning industries. To hear the 
 representatives of both these industries, one, not knowing any better, 
 would have been convinced that the most healthful, remunerative, edu- 
 cational place in the entire world in which to develop children was in a 
 cotton mill or an oyster cannery. One fairly tingled to spend the rest 
 of life shucking oysters or peeling shrimp." Supplement, Annals 
 of the Am. Acad. of Political and Social Science, March, 1909. Jean M. 
 Gordon: The Forward Step in Louisiana, p. 163. 
 
 3 Census Report, Manufactures. 1905, Part I., p. ccxxx. 
 
 Ibid., pp. ccxxx. and ccxxxi. (computed). 
 
324 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The principal inducement for locating new shoe factories in 
 rural sections of Missouri appears to be the availability of 
 cheap labor of native American women and children, who 
 can underbid the male immigrants employed in the shoe 
 factories of Massachusetts. 
 
" CHAPTER XV 
 
 LABOR ORGANIZATIONS 
 
 Immigration Commission has made the statement 
 1 that " the recent immigrant has not, as a rule, affiliated 
 himself with labor unions, unless compelled to do so as a 
 preliminary step toward acquiring work. . . . Where he 
 has united with the labor organizations he has usually 
 refused to maintain his membership for any extended period 
 of time, thus rendering difficult the unionizing of the occu- 
 pation or industry in which he has been engaged.'* This 
 assertion could be proved only by a statistical study of the 
 membership of labor organizations. It is a characteristic 
 fact that with a Federal Bureau of Labor and a number of 
 State labor bureaus we have no compilation of the total 
 number of organized workers in the United States for a 
 series of years. x A great deal of information on the subject 
 is scattered in the published reports of labor conventions. 
 The inevitable gaps could be supplied from the records of 
 labor organizations. The Immigration Commission, how- 
 ever, made no effort to secure statistics of union member- 
 ship in a systematic way from official sources, but confined 
 its inquiries in the main to the heads of the households 
 covered by its investigation. The report of the Commission 
 contains data concerning 3325 trade unionists, whereas the 
 total membership of labor organizations in the United States 
 was estimated for 1910 at 2,625,000. * The reports of the 
 Commission contain a few fragmentary data on the member- 
 ship of labor organizations, apparently obtained from their 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xvii., p. xviii. 
 *New York Labor Bulletin, September, 1911, p. 418. 
 
 325 
 
326 Immigration and Labor 
 
 officials, but these data flatly contradict the conclusions of 
 the Commission. 
 
 We learn that "practically 36 per cent of the total number 
 of clothing workers in New York are organized; while 80 
 per cent of the cutters are members of the cutters' union. 
 Of the organized workers, about 60 per cent are Russian and 
 Polish Hebrews, 30 per cent Italians, and 10 per cent persons 
 of other races including foreign and native-born." 1 To 
 understand the meaning of these percentages, we must 
 compare them with the percentage of organized workers in 
 all industries. The total number of male industrial wage- 
 earners in the United States at the census of 1900 can be 
 estimated at 8,600,000 2 ; since very few women are affiliated 
 with labor organizations the number of males alone need 
 be taken into consideration in computing the percentage of 
 organized workers. The increase of the population of the 
 United States from 1 900 to 1 9 1 o was 2 1 per cent. The num- 
 ber of male industrial wage-earners in 1910 can accordingly 
 be estimated at 10,400,000, and the proportion of organized 
 workingmen in all industries at 25 per cent. Thus while, 
 on an average, only 25 per cent of all male wage-eairners in 
 the United States were affiliated with labor organizations, 
 among the clothing workers in New York City 36 per cent 
 were organized, all but one tenth of the organized workers 
 being Russian and Polish Hebrews and Italians. Of the 
 most skilled among them, the cutters, 80 per cent were mem- 
 bers of their union, i.e., relatively thrice as many as in all 
 industries of the country at large. 
 
 Of course, the question is whether the condition in the 
 clothing industry of New York may be accepted as typical. 
 The reports of the Immigration Commission furnish no 
 comparable data for the industries of the country at large. 
 The results of the study of households comprise less than 
 two trade-unionists in every 1000. Still, this being the only 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission? vol. II, p. 388. 
 2 1. A. Hourwich, " Social -Economic Classes of the Population of the 
 United States," Journal of Political Economy, March, 1911, p. 205. 
 
Labor Organizations 327 
 
 statistical evidence which the Immigration Commission has 
 produced in support of its conclusions regarding the attitude 
 of recent immigrants toward trade unions, it is worthy of 
 note that upon the Commission's own showing trade- 
 unionism is as strong among the immigrants as among the 
 native American workmen. The ratio of organized workers 
 to all male wage-earners in each population group is shown 
 in Table 96. 
 
 TABLE 96. 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF NATIVE AND IMMIGRANT LABOR. 1 
 
 _ Nativity of wage-earners 
 
 Native-born of native father: 
 
 White ............................................ 13 .9 
 
 Negro ............................................ 17.9 
 
 Native-born of foreign father ....................... . . 14.1 
 
 Foreign-born ........................................ 13 .4 
 
 While on the whole trade-unionism is very weak in the 
 field covered by the investigation of the Commission, it is 
 manifest from the practical uniformity of the percentages 
 for each group that distinctions of birth, race, and color do 
 not explain this weakness. 
 
 Neither could a line be drawn in respect of unionism be- 
 tween the " desirable " immigrants from Northern and West- 
 ern Europe and the "undesirable aliens from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe. " This fact is brought to light by the com- 
 parison in Table 97 of the principal immigrant races that are 
 represented by at least 500 persons each 2 in the statistics 
 of the Immigration Commission. On the whole, the aver- 
 age percentage of union men among the "undesirable aliens" 
 is higher than among the immigrants of the preferred races. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 417. 
 
 a Smaller groups have been omitted because, where the numbers are 
 small, the ratios are liable to be influenced by exceptional circumstances 
 and local conditions; for example, the highest percentage of organized 
 workmen, 100 per cent, was found among the Mexicans, because the 
 investigators of the Commission chanced to come across 56 Mexican 
 miners in a unionized mine. Ibid., pp. 418-419. 
 
328 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 97- 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF IMMIGRANT LABOR 1 
 
 'Desirable" races 
 
 Total 
 number 
 
 Organized 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 
 573 
 
 524 
 724 
 
 515 
 
 537 
 
 I,IOI 
 
 133 
 87 
 107 
 
 48 
 26 
 
 51 
 
 23.2 
 16.6 
 14.8 
 9-3 
 4-8 
 4.6 
 
 
 Irish 
 
 Swedish 
 
 
 German 
 
 
 Total 
 
 3.974 
 
 452 
 
 II.4 
 
 
 "Undesirable" races 
 North Italian 
 
 881 
 1,408 
 761 
 684 
 1,706 
 2,428 
 
 1,501 
 3,280 
 
 351 
 
 497 
 163 
 144 
 
 234 
 258 
 146 
 313 
 
 39-8 
 
 35-3 
 21.4 
 
 21. 1 
 
 13.7 
 10.5 
 
 9-7 
 9-5 
 
 
 Hebrew 
 
 Ruthenian 
 
 Slovak 
 
 South Italian 
 
 Magyar 
 
 polish 
 
 
 Total 
 
 12,649 
 
 2,106 
 
 16.6 
 
 
 The percentage of trade-unionists among North Italians is 
 nearly three times as high as among native Americans of 
 native parentage; the Lithuanians furnish twice as many 
 as the more desirable Englishmen; the Hebrews twice as 
 many as the Swedes; the Ruthenians are far ahead of the 
 Americans of native stock; even the South Italians can 
 boast a percentage twice as high as the Germans; the Mag- 
 yars and the Slovaks march in front of the Swedes; and the 
 Poles, who are at the tail end of the procession of undesirables 
 from Eastern Europe, still outnumber two to one their more 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 418. 
 
Labor Organizations 329 
 
 favored kinsmen, the Bohemians and Moravians. Con- 
 sidering that the native Americans and the members of the 
 races which contributed most largely to the earlier immi- 
 gration are, as a rule, engaged in higher occupations, where 
 they are for the most part segregated from the recent immi- 
 grants, it is clear that the latter could not be an obstacle in 
 the way of organization among the skilled men ; and that they 
 have not been an obstacle is shown by the fact that the re- 
 cent immigrants themselves furnish a higher percentage of 
 organized workmen. 
 
 As usual, when the facts do not fit its theory, the Com- 
 mission seeks to qualify the plain language of the figures: 
 
 These figures must not, however, be taken as representative of racial 
 tendencies except in a few cases, for the reason that the information 
 shown for one race may be for but one or two industries in which the 
 race is employed and which are so controlled by labor organizations that 
 membership in the labor unions is necessary to secure employment. 
 On the other hand, a race or several races may be employed in an indus- 
 try or industries in which no labor unions exist. . . . The fact that 
 certain races are most extensively employed in highly unionized 
 localities and industries is indicative of comparatively greater 
 assimilation and progressiveness on the part of the members of such 
 races. 1 
 
 The Commission thus assumes that affiliation of immi- 
 grants with labor organizations is a sign of their "assimi- 
 lation, " which implies that organization of labor is a native 
 growth, and that the foreigner merely imitates the ways of 
 the native. This view has no foundation in the history of 
 organized labor in the United States. The fact is that the 
 membership of most of the labor organizations has from 
 their inception been very largely foreign-born. 
 
 Historians have traced the embryo of labor organization 
 in America to the colonial period. Labor organizations 
 sprang up here and there during the first quarter of the 
 nineteenth century. Between 1825 and 1850 a number of 
 labor conventions were held. But all labor organizations 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 419. 
 
330 Immigration and Labor 
 
 before the Civil War were ephemeral and soon disintegrated. 
 Their effect upon economic conditions was negligible. x 
 
 The depreciation of the currency and the consequent 
 rise of the cost of living during the Civil War stimulated 
 organization among workmen. Still the figures made acces- 
 sible by the research of Dr. Fite "plainly caution the 
 present generation against exaggerating the importance of 
 the war-time unions; they were numerous and bold in 
 leadership, but they were small in membership and em- 
 braced only a small part of the labor world. " 2 
 
 The plan of the X. Census comprised an inquiry into the 
 subject of trade unions in the United States. The statisti- 
 cal data collected were fragmentary. The development of 
 labor organizations up to 1880 is summed up as follows: 
 
 "But very few of the unions reported upon, so far as their 
 age could be learned, have had a long existence. The his- 
 tory of unionism in most cases is that an organization is 
 effected under the stress of some difficulty, flourishes for a 
 while, and then dies out, to be brought to life again in case 
 of urgent need." 3 
 
 Five years later, Col. Richard J. Hinton, a strong labor 
 sympathizer, contrasting the British with the American 
 labor organizations, noted with regret that "in the United 
 States the whole movement has hardly reached the stage of 
 toleration." 4 
 
 Official inquiries made about the same time in Illinois 
 (1886) and New Jersey (1887) established the fact that the 
 majority of the trade-unionists and Knights of Labor were 
 
 1 Mass. Report on Statistics of Labor, 1906, "The Incorporation of 
 Trade Unions," Part. III., pp. 131-134. Frank Tracy Carlton. The 
 History and Problems of Organized Labor, p. 41. 
 
 Emerson David Fite: Social and Industrial Conditions during the 
 Civil War, pp. 204-205. 
 
 * X. 'Census, vol. xx. Report on Trade Societies in the United States, p. 3. 
 
 Richard J. Hinton, "American Labor Organizations," The North 
 American Review, January, 1885, p. 49. ~An official report for the same 
 year states that "trade unions in America are in their infancy yet." 
 Ninth Annual Report of the Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics (1885, p. 20). 
 
Labor Organizations 331 
 
 of foreign birth, whereas the native Americans contributed 
 less than their quota to the membership of labor organiza- 
 tions. 1 This fact had been generally known before from 
 common ^observation. In the report of the New Jersey 
 Bureau of Statistics of Labor for 1884, immigration was 
 held directly responsible for the organization of labor unions. 
 The writer of an article on "Immigration and the Labor 
 Problem, " after stating that native Americans are displaced 
 by laborers "coming from countries in which wages are 
 lower than our standard" and where the standard of living 
 is therefore lower, goes on to say that 
 
 to the American laborer of twenty-five or thirty years since, such an 
 occurrence would have been an inconvenience but not altogether a dis- 
 aster. Failing to obtain the work he wanted at one place or in one trade, 
 he would turn to another and yet another, until he had found something 
 by which he could live. But the foreign-born operative has but little 
 of this cat-like facility of falling upon his feet. He knows but a single 
 trade; often, in the subdivision of mechanical employments, which is 
 almost uniformily prevalent and becoming still more so, only a small 
 fraction of that. Thrown out of his place, he must find another almost 
 precisely similar, or acquire a new training by a slow and painful process, 
 during which he earns little or nothing, and he has in far the greater 
 number of cases nothing laid up. That men should grow desperate and 
 wicked under such circumstances is not surprising. That they should 
 combine in leagues of various kinds; limit the hours of labor, or the 
 amount of work to be done in a given time; refuse to work with appren- 
 tices, or men outside of their own associations; strike, and agree not 
 only to remain idle themselves, but to prevent others from working; . . . 
 is the most natural thing in the world. 2 
 
 Thus, as late as 1884, the organization of labor unions was 
 decried in a State report as un-American, the work of foreign- 
 ers grown "desperate and wicked." Ten years later the 
 Minnesota Bureau of Labor undertook an investigation to 
 disprove that view. It is instructive to contrast the state 
 of public opinion in the early go's as reflected in the report 
 
 x The results of those inquiries are given in the Appendix, Table XXII. 
 Seventh A nnual Report of the New Jersey Bureau of Statistics of Labor 
 and Industries (1884), pp. 289-290. 
 
332 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the Minnesota Labor Bureau, with the sentiment of our 
 own day, when a Congressional commission regards unionism 
 as a manifestation of Americanism : 
 
 It has been repeatedly charged by a certain class of writers that 
 American trade unions are conspiracies to prevent American boys from 
 acquiring skilled crafts. This charge has been most clearly stated by 
 the Century Magazine, May, 1893. It says: "Under the present con- 
 ditions of trade instruction and employment in this country the Ameri- 
 can boy has no rights which organized labor is bound to respect. He is 
 denied instruction as an apprentice, and if he be taught his trade in a 
 trade school he is refused admission to nearly all trade unions and is boy- 
 cotted if he attempts to work as a non-union man. The questions of his 
 character and skill enter into the matter only to discriminate against 
 him. All the trade unions of the country are controlled by foreigners, 
 who comprise the great body of their members; while they refuse ad- 
 mission to the trained American boy, they admit all foreign applicants 
 with little or no regard to their training or skill. In fact the doors of 
 organized labor in America, which are closed and barred against Ameri- 
 can boys, swing open wide and free to all foreign-comers. Labor in free 
 America is free to all save sons of Americans. " The same magazine, in its 
 issue of July , 1 893 , says : ' ' They (the trade unions) are afraid of America 's 
 independent ideas in their unions, knowing, as they do, that American 
 workmen are not so servile and not so easily led as the more ignorant 
 foreign workmen. " a 
 
 The report of the Minnesota Bureau of Labor then pro- 
 ceeds to disprove, by figures relative to Minnesota labor 
 unions, the statements made in the Century articles. It 
 shows that in the three large cities of the State 62 per cent 
 of males of voting age at the census of 1890 were foreign- 
 born, whereas of the total number of trade unionists who 
 replied to the inquiries of the Bureau, 58.54 per cent were 
 
 1 Fourth Biennial Report of the Minnesota Bureau of Labor (1893-94), 
 
 P- 175- 
 
 3 The author of a doctor's dissertation, submitted to the University 
 of Chicago at the same time, strongly advocated restriction of immi- 
 gration, to ward off a "peril" which threatened American labor in "the 
 fact that our trade unions are almost exclusively controlled by foreigners 
 . . . incapable by long oppression in the industrial slavery of Europe 
 to understand or appreciate the true dignity or interests of American 
 labor. " Rena M. Atchison : Un-A merican Immigration, p. 1 05. 
 
Labor Organizations 333 
 
 born in the United States and 41.46 per cent were foreign- 
 born. But a table in the report shows 1 1 of the unions with 
 more than 62 per cent of foreign-born members. Those 
 trades were the granite cutters with 70.09, bricklayers with 
 72.10, tailors with 100, bakers with loo, carpenters with 
 75-75 stonecutters with 72.75, blacksmiths with 100 per 
 cent of foreign-born members. 
 
 The change of public sentiment from 1894, when the 
 "ignorant foreign workmen" were accused of organizing 
 labor unions, to 1910, when the ignorant foreigners were 
 accused of keeping away from labor unions, is symptomatic 
 of the progress of organized labor during the intervening 
 period. In 1894, when the "ignorant foreigners" com- 
 prised mainly the races of "the old immigration," trade 
 unionism was still weak; after eighteen years of "undesir- 
 able immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe," 
 organized labor has gained in numbers and won public 
 recognition. 
 
 An idea of the comparative strength of labor organizations 
 in the days of the old and the new immigration can be gained 
 from the distribution of the number of existing unions by the 
 period of their organizations, as shown in Table 98. 
 
 Very few of the existing unions were organized prior to 
 1880. The work of organization has since been proceeding 
 at an increasing rate of speed. During the first decade of 
 the new immigration, 1880-1890, more unions were organ- 
 ized and survived than throughout the whole previous his- 
 tory of the United States. In the next decade, 1890-1900, 
 when immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe first 
 outran "the old immigration," the number of new unions 
 organized in five of the six States (all but Illinois) exceeded 
 the total number of unions which had survived from pre- 
 vious times. But the greatest success rewarded the efforts 
 of union organizers during the first decade of the present 
 century. In Massachusetts, Connecticut, and Minnesota 
 more new unions were organized since 1900 than during the 
 whole ninteenth century. It must be borne in mind that 
 
334 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Massachusetts and Connecticut have received large ac- 
 cessions to their population from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe. Thus the greatest activity in the field of organiza- 
 tion coincided with the unparalleled new immigration of 
 the past decade. 
 
 TABLE 98. 
 
 NUMBER AND DATE OF ORGANIZATION OF ACTIVE LABOR UNIONS IN SIX 
 INDUSTRIAL STATES. 1 
 
 
 1 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 5 
 
 Period 
 
 g 
 
 t> 
 
 
 at 
 
 "jj 
 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 1 
 
 B 
 
 6 
 
 1 
 
 | 
 
 1 
 
 a 
 
 ii 
 
 Total number: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Prior to 1880. . . 
 
 32 
 
 24 
 
 40 
 
 65 
 
 40 
 
 ii 
 
 1880-1889 
 
 116 
 
 6i 
 
 126 
 
 254 
 
 75 
 
 62 
 
 1800-1800. . . 
 
 107 
 
 1 08 
 
 7IO 
 
 278 
 
 24.1 
 
 107 
 
 Since 1900 
 
 6583 
 
 
 
 
 24.1 
 
 107 s 
 
 Annual average: 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1880-1889 
 
 12 
 
 6 
 
 1 1 
 
 2 r 
 
 8 
 
 6 
 
 1800-1800. . . 
 
 2O 
 
 ii 
 
 71 
 
 28 
 
 24. 
 
 
 Since 1900 
 
 71 
 
 28 
 
 
 QI 6 
 
 
 22 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 The aggregate membership of labor organizations in the 
 United States and Canada was estimated by the Industrial 
 Commission at 1,300,000 for July i, I9OI. 7 The aggregate 
 
 'Compiled from Report on Statistics of Labor, Massachusetts, 1908, 
 pp. 185-186. Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics, 24th Annual Report, 
 1900, p. 297. Minnesota Labor Report, 1905-6, p. 365; ibid., 1907-8, p. 
 83. Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics of Illinois, 1886, p. 198; 
 ibid., 1901, p. 298. Report of the Connecticut Bureau of Labor Sta- 
 tistics, 1909-1910, p. 217. J2d Annual Report of the Missouri Bureau of 
 Labor. a Periods: Up to 1880; 1881-1890; 1891-1900; 1901-1908. 
 
 * 1900-1908. < 1900-1909. s 1900-1908. 6 In 1900-1901 183. 
 
 7 The total membership of enumerated unions was estimated at 
 1,208,000, to which was added an arbitrary allowance of 191,100 for 
 the Knights of Labor "and unenumerated organizations. " The former 
 were at the time in a moribund condition, and the Industrial Commission 
 believed that its estimate was subject to a probable error of 100,000. 
 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xvii., p. xix. 
 
Labor Organizations 335 
 
 membership of all unions in 1910 was estimated by the New 
 York Bureau of Labor at 2,625,000 for the United States 
 and Canada. 1 Thus in nine years from 1901 to 1910, with 
 their unprecedented immigration, the membership of la- 
 bor organizations doubled, whereas the average number 
 of wage-earners employed in manufactures increased from 
 
 1899 to 1909 only about 40 per cent, 2 the number of 
 railway employees from 1900 to 1910, 67 per cent, 3 etc. 
 
 The reports of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics 
 since 1897 furnish a record of the annual increase or decrease 
 of union membership, which permits of a comparative study 
 of the relation between trade-unionism and immigration. 
 New York State is the receptacle of more than its propor- 
 tionate share of "the new immigration." New York City 
 is a temporary stopping-place for many a stranded immi- 
 grant lacking the funds for continuing his journey to final 
 destination. The evil effects of immigration, if such they 
 be, must appear in aggravated form in the State of New 
 York. The relation between union membership and immi- 
 gration is shown graphically in Diagram XX. 4 The curves 
 representing trade-union membership and the immigration 
 of breadwinners 5 run almost parallel, showing that union 
 
 1 New York Labor Bulletin, Sept., 1911, p. 418. 
 
 2 XIII. Census, volume viii. Manufactures, p. 240. The real 
 increase of the average number of wage-earners is smaller, because the 
 number for 1910 is the average of 12 monthly pay-rolls, whereas in 
 
 1900 the average number was computed "by using 12, the number of 
 calendar months, as a divisor into the total of the average numbers 
 reported for each month. " The effect of this change of method is shown 
 in the case of twelve selected industries, where the average number 
 computed "as an abstract unit (like the foot-pound)" was 475,473, 
 whereas the total "computed on the basis of time in operation would 
 have exceeded 650,000, " the variation being as high as 36 per cent. 
 XII. Census. Manufactures, Part I., pp. cvi., ex., cxi. 
 
 * Interstate Commerce Commission. Twenty-third Annual Report 
 tf the Statistics of Railways, pp. 33-34. 
 
 The figures from which the latter is plotted will be found in the 
 Appendix, Table XXIII. 
 
 A11 immigrants save those that have "no occupation (including 
 women and children)," in official terminology. 
 
336 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 membership rises and falls as immigration rises and falls. 
 The New York statistics thus disprove the conclusion of the 
 
 DIAGRAM XX. 
 
 r~ 
 
 b 
 
 ^ 
 
 a 
 
 \_ 
 
 /: 
 
 XX. Labor union membership in the State of New York, number of 
 
 immigrant bread-winners destined for the State of New York 
 
 and combined imports and exports through the port of 
 
 New York. 1897-1910. 
 
 Immigration Commission that "liis (the recent immigrant's) 
 availability and his general characteristics and attitude have 
 constituted a passive opposition which has been most 
 
Labor Organizations 337 
 
 effective." 1 The third curve represents the aggregate ex- 
 ports and imports through the port of New York. The 
 import and export trade of New York gives employment, 
 directly and indirectly, to a large portion of the population 
 of the city. It feeds the traffic of all railways in the State 
 with terminals in New York. The fluctuations of the export 
 trade may therefore be taken as an index of the business 
 situation in the State of New York. It will be observed that 
 the curve of union membership follows very closely the 
 curve of foreign trade. The fluctuations of union member- 
 ship accordingly depend upon the business situation. The 
 latter likewise determines the fluctuations of immigration. 
 The harmonious movement of immigration and organiza- 
 tion among workers is thus accounted for by the fact that 
 both are stimulated by business prosperity and discouraged 
 by business depression. 
 
 The question may be raised, however: given the indus- 
 trial expansion of the past decade, would not the progress of 
 trade-unionism have been greater "without the availability 
 of the recent immigrant labor supply"? An answer to this 
 question is furnished by the comparative statistics of union 
 membership in the States of New York and Kansas for 1900- 
 1909. While New York has received great numbers of 
 immigrants during this period, the ratio of foreign-born in 
 Kansas has been steadily decreasing since 1880: in the 
 latter year the ratio was n per cent, in 1910 only 8 per 
 cent. The proportion of foreign-born from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe to the population of Kansas was only 2 per 
 cent. 2 At the same time Kansas has shared in the indus- 
 trial expansion of the period, as witnessed by the amounts 
 paid out in wages to factory operatives in 1899 an( ^ i99 
 shown in Table 99. While the increase in the United States 
 at large amounted to 71 per cent and in New York City to 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i., p. 541. 
 
 2 Statistical Abstract, 1910, Table 25, p. 53. XIII. Census. Popula- 
 tion, vol. i., p. 817; vol. ii., p. 669. 
 
338 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 65 per cent, in Kansas it reached 100 per cent. The 
 comparative growth of trade-unionism in New York and 
 Kansas in 1900-1909 must accordingly reveal the effects of 
 
 TABLE 99. 
 
 TOTAL WAGES PAID TO FACTORY OPERATIVES IN THE UNITED STATES AND 
 IN THE STATES OF NEW YORK AND KANSAS (MILLIONS OF 
 
 DOLLARS), 1899 AND 1909. x 
 
 
 1899 
 
 1909 
 
 Per cent 
 of increase 
 
 United States 
 
 2008 
 
 ^427 
 
 71 
 
 New York . 
 
 7 
 
 Gey 
 
 6& 
 
 Kansas 
 
 I* 
 
 26 
 
 100 
 
 
 
 
 
 industrial expansion upon the progress of organization 
 among the wage-earners, with and without the availability 
 of the recent immigrant. 
 
 Table 100 shows the ratio of organized workers in each 
 of the two States to its total urban population. 2 The 
 relative number of organized workmen is higher in New 
 York with a large and growing immigrant population 
 drawn from Southern and Eastern Europe than in Kansas 
 with a small and decreasing foreign-born population. 
 Prior to the recent crisis the percentage of organized 
 workmen in New York was more than twice as high as in 
 Kansas. The industrial depression of 1909 reduced the 
 percentage of organized workmen in New York, while in 
 Kansas the year 1908 was a record year for labor organiz- 
 ations. Yet even then the proportion of organized work- 
 men in New York remained higher than in Kansas. 
 
 1 XIII. Census, vol. viii. Manufactures, Table III, pp. 542, 543. 
 
 * Urban population is defined by the census as "that residing in cities 
 and other incorporated places of 2500 inhabitants or more." (XIII. 
 Census, vol. i. Population, p. 53.) The population for 1900 is that 
 enumerated by the census. The urban population for each subsequent 
 year is estimated in accordance with the method followed by the United 
 
Labor Organizations 
 
 339 
 
 TABLE loo. 
 
 PER CENT RATIO OF TRADE-UNION MEMBERSHIP TO URBAN POPULATION 
 IN NSW YORE AND KANSAS, 1900-1909.* 
 
 Year 
 
 New York 
 
 Kansas 
 
 1900 
 
 4.6 
 
 1-9 
 
 1901 
 
 5-0 
 
 2-3 
 
 1902 
 
 5-8 
 
 2.1 
 
 1903 
 
 6-7 
 
 2.6 
 
 1904 
 
 6.4 
 
 3<> 
 
 1905 
 
 6.1 
 
 3<> 
 
 1906 
 
 6.2 
 
 2.8 
 
 1907 
 
 6.6 
 
 2.9 
 
 1908 
 
 5-5 
 
 5-2 
 
 1909 
 
 5-3 
 
 4.4 
 
 The preceding ratios may be affected by the character of 
 the urban population in the two States : if the proportion of 
 wage-earners to the whole population in New York was 
 higher than in Kansas, the difference might in a measure 
 account for the higher percentage of organized workmen. 
 These doubts are resolved by Diagram XXI., which shows 
 for each State the ratio of union membership to the num- 
 ber of industrial wage-earners at the XII. Census. 2 The 
 curve for New York runs throughout the whole period 
 above that for Kansas. 
 
 These differences are by no means accidental. In the 
 early period of trade-unionism in the United States, when it 
 was generally regarded as a "foreign" plant and denounced 
 as "un-American," contemporary observers sought to ex- 
 plain the aloofness of the native American wage-earners 
 from labor organizations by their "indisposition to identify 
 themselves permanently with any class." 
 
 The foreign workman has the tradition of many generations and the 
 walls of caste to restrain him within certain limits as to his occupation; 
 
 States Bureau of Statistics, by adding to the population of the preceding 
 year one tenth of the increase from 1900 to 1910. 
 
 * See Appendix, Table XXIV. a Ibid. 
 
DIAGRAM XXI. 
 
 - s 
 
 \ 
 
 s 
 
 XXI. Male union membership in the states of New York and 
 Kansas, 1900-1909; Per cent ratio to the number of in- 
 dustrial wage-earners in 1900. 
 340 
 
Labor Organizations 341 
 
 he has no possibilities beyond a given sphere, and is trained and de- 
 veloped within it. Thus environed, his career and ambitions lie in the 
 paths his fathers have trod, and his associations with his fellow craftsmen 
 make the trade union his natural and necessary place. Transported to 
 this country he brings his feelings for the union and his class associa- 
 tions with him as a habit. But the American mechanic's boy is born to 
 no conditions in life from which he may not rise, of hope to rise, or 
 which at least he may not abandon for better or worse. All the pre- 
 cepts of the schools and teachings of observation suggest other ways of 
 making a living, or at least other avenues in life, than those of his 
 father.* 
 
 In a later publication of the Massachusetts Labor Bureau 
 the unstable character of trade unions in New England up 
 to 1880 is explained by the fact "that early New England 
 workmen seldom regarded their condition as journeymen as 
 likely to be permanent. They nearly all looked forward 
 with some degree of hope to a time when they would become 
 employers."* 
 
 This condition still exists in smaller communities where 
 many of the native American wage-earners are home-own- 
 ers, 3 and in country districts where the factory workers are 
 drawn from the farms of the neighborhood. As a result, we 
 find labor better organized in New York City with a high 
 percentage of recent immigrants than in the remainder 
 of the State of New York, with a predominantly native 
 population. 
 
 In Table 101, the distribution of male trade-union mem- 
 bership between the city of New York and the remainder of 
 the State is presented in parallel columns with the distribu- 
 tion of male breadwinners in non-agricultural pursuits. 
 
 In New York City one half of all breadwinners in 1900 
 were foreign-born, whereas in the remainder of the State 
 three fourths were of native birth. At the same time New 
 York City had more than its proportionate share of trade- 
 
 1 Fourth Annual Report of the Illinois Bureau of Statistics of Labor 
 (1886), p. 228. 
 
 * Massachusetts Labor Bulletin, No. 10, April, 1899, p. 55. 
 Pratt, he. cit., p. 99. 
 
342 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 101. 
 
 COMPARATIVE UNION MEMBERSHIP IN THE STATE OF NEW YORK AND IN 
 THE CITY OF NEW YORK, I9OO. 1 
 
 Geographical 
 division 
 
 Union membership 
 (male) 
 
 Male breadwinners in non- 
 agricultural pursuits 
 per cent 
 
 Thousands 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Ail 
 
 Nativities 
 
 Foreign-born 
 Ratio to total 
 
 State 
 
 234 
 146 
 88 
 
 100 
 62 
 
 38 
 
 100 
 
 56 
 44 
 
 
 New York City 
 
 11 
 
 Outside of New York City 
 
 union membership. The margin in favor of New York City 
 would be still greater if instead of all breadwinners indus- 
 trial wage-earners alone were considered, the proportion of 
 the latter being larger outside of the great cities than in 
 cities with a population of over 3oo,ooo. 2 
 
 The figures are for the year 1900. The conditions have 
 not changed since, as appears from Table 102 on p. 
 
 343- 
 
 The membership of the trade unions in New York City 
 more than doubled from 1900 to 1910, whereas in the re- 
 mainder of the State it increased by less than three fifths. 
 This difference was not due to a proportionate increase of 
 the population of New York City compared with the urban 
 population of the remainder of the State: while the popu- 
 lation of New York City increased somewhat faster than 
 the urban population outside of New York City, the relative 
 number of organized workers in New York City increased 
 still faster. The figures furnish unmistakable evidence of 
 greater progress of trade unions at the gate of the United 
 States, parallel with the growth of the foreign-born popu- 
 
 1 Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1910, vol. ii., pp. 
 xlix., L, 15. Occupations, XII. Census, Tables 41 and 43. 
 
 Hourwich, loc. cit.. Journal of Political Economy, April, 1911, 
 P- 324- 
 
Labor Organizations 
 
 343 
 
 TABLE 102. 
 
 COMPARATIVE UNION MEMBERSHIP IN THE STATE OF NEW YORK AND IN 
 THE CITY OF NEW YORK, 1 900-1910. x 
 
 Both sexes 
 
 Year 
 
 State 
 
 New York 
 City 
 
 Outside of 
 New York 
 City 
 
 Union membership: 
 
 Absolute number 
 u 
 
 Increase 
 
 1900 
 1910 
 
 Thousands 
 
 245 
 
 48-2 
 Per cent 
 
 Thousands 
 
 154 
 338 
 Per cent 
 
 no 
 
 Thousands 
 
 91 
 144 
 
 Per cent 
 V8 
 
 Relative number: 
 
 <! II 
 
 Urban population: 
 
 Foreign-born white: 
 Ratio to urban 
 
 1900 
 1910 
 1900 
 1910 
 
 IQOO 
 
 100 
 100 
 100 
 100 
 
 63 
 
 1 
 64 
 
 66 
 37 
 
 37 
 30 
 36 
 34 
 
 2* 
 
 
 IOIO 
 
 
 4.O 
 
 2 1 * 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 lation, than in the remainder of the State where eight 
 ninths of the population are American-born. 
 
 Still, the strength of organized labor is measured above 
 mere numbers by its ability to marshal its forces in con- 
 tests over terms of employment. The strike statistics 
 which have been collected by the United States Bureau of 
 Labor do not extend to the period prior to 1881, but there 
 are official figures for Massachusetts going as far back as 
 1830, and for Pennsylvania as far as 1835. The data are 
 presented in Table 103 on the next page: 
 
 1 Report of the New York Bureau of Labor Statistics ; 1910, vol. ii., pp. 
 xlix., 1., 15. XIII. Census. Population, vol. i., pp. 179, 191 (computed). 
 
344 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 103. 
 
 NUMBER OF STRIKES IN MASSACHUSETTS, 1830-1905, AND PENNSYLVANIA, 
 
 1835-1905. ' 
 
 
 Massachusetts 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 Period: 
 Prior to 1880 
 
 ISO 
 
 IS2 
 
 1881-1905: 
 Total 
 Annual average 
 
 2774 
 III 
 
 4156 
 
 166 
 
 
 
 
 Making every allowance for the incompleteness of the re- 
 ports of early strikes, we see once more from the figures for 
 two of the leading industrial States that in the days of "the 
 old immigration*' the labor movement was negligible: the 
 average number of strikes in Pennsylvania during one year 
 since 1881 exceeds the total for the preceding half -century. 
 
 In order to trace the effect, if any, of the new immigration 
 upon the strike movement, the period 1896-1905, when 
 immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe became 
 predominant, is next compared with the ten-year period 
 next preceding. 
 
 Table 104 shows an increase of the number of strikers in 
 general, and of organized strikers in particular. Taking the 
 number of industrial wage-earners in 1890 as the average 
 for 1886-1895 and the number in 1900 as the average for 
 1896-1905, we find an increase of 34 per cent 2 ; the annual 
 average number of strikers increased at the same time 
 29 per cent, and the annual average of organized strikers 
 38 per cent. In other words. the strike movement kept 
 
 1 Eleventh Annual Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics of Massa- 
 chusetts, 1880, p. 65. Report of the Secretary of the Internal Affairs of 
 Pennsylvania, Part III., Industrial Statistics, 1880-1881, p. 388. 
 Twenty-first Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, 1906, pp. 492- 
 495- 
 
 a Hourwich, loc, cit. Journal of Political Economy, March, 1911, 
 p. 213. 
 
Labor Organizations 
 
 345 
 
 TABLE 104. 
 
 STRIKES AND IMMIGRATION OF BREADWINNERS BY DECENNIAL PERIODS, 
 
 1 886-1 905.' 
 
 Period 
 
 Annual average number (thousands) 
 
 Percent of estab- 
 lishments in which 
 strikes failed 
 
 Immigrant 
 bread 
 winners 
 
 Strikers 
 
 Total 
 
 Organized 
 
 Unorgan- 
 ized 
 
 Organ- 
 ized 
 
 Unorgan- 
 ized 
 
 1886-1895 
 
 241 
 
 389 
 
 26 7 
 
 344 
 
 208 
 287 
 
 59 
 
 57 
 
 41.8 
 29.6 
 
 55-2 
 58.4 
 
 1806-1005 
 
 
 pace with the growing number of industrial wage-earners. 
 The percentage of unsuccessful organized strikes decreased. 
 The movement was apparently not affected either by 
 the increase of immigration, or by the change in its racial 
 make-up. 
 
 Immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe have at 
 times acted as strike breakers, but so have native Ameri- 
 cans. 2 In 1904, during the strike of the miners of the Ala- 
 bama district, "the operators brought in Magyars, Slovaks, 
 Greeks, Servians, Italians, and Finns, as well as native 
 whites, as strike breakers." 3 It is a matter of common 
 
 1 XXI. Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table IV, pp. 478- 
 479, and Table V, pp. 490-491. Reports of the Commissioner-General of 
 Immigration, 1903-1905. Summary of Commerce and Finance, June 
 1903, pp. 4422-4423. Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, p- 
 246, Table 150. 
 
 3 In the big strike of 1877 "many American girls, it was said, acted 
 as strike breakers, replacing Bohemian women. " In the cigar industry, 
 in general, "when immigrant women went on strike they were replaced 
 -with comparative ease by American girls. " Report of Woman and Child 
 Wage-Earners in the United States, vol. ix., p. 199-201. 
 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, p. 197. In 1908, 
 
 ''during the strike [of the miners of Birmingham], considerable numbers 
 
 of immigrants were brought in as strike breakers, but in not so great a 
 
 proportion as native whites from other coal-mining sections. " Ibid., 
 
 , 2pp, 
 
346 Immigration and Labor 
 
 knowledge, however, that in many strikes of national 
 dimensions, most of the participants were immigrants 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 
 The Immigration Commission has given expression to the 
 popular condemnation of the Southern and Eastern 
 European immigrants for their alleged "tractability" and 
 their "willingness seemingly to accept indefinitely without 
 protest certain wages and conditions of employment." 1 It 
 is worthy of note that the same criticism was directed against 
 English immigrants when they were among the "new 
 immigration." The following, from a labor paper published 
 in 1845, has a familiar sound: 
 
 Capital is striving to fill the country with foreign workmen. 
 English workmen, whose abject condition in their own country has made 
 them tame, submissive and "peaceable orderly citizens"; that is, work 14 
 and 16 hours per day, for what capital sees fit to give them, and if it is 
 not enough to provide them a comfortable house to shelter their wives 
 and children and furnish them with decent food and clothes, why they 
 must live in cellars, go hungry and ragged. 3 
 
 To-day the complaint against the immigrants from South- 
 ern and Eastern Europe who are "mainly, unskilled 
 laborers," is that "on the whole" they "have not shown 
 the same readiness to join trade-unions ... as have those 
 coming from the older immigration from the north and west 
 of Europe." 3 In general, as shown, the supposed connec- 
 tion between trade-unionism and the points of the compass 
 is not sustained by the statistics of the Immigration Com- 
 mission. In regard to unskilled laborers, in particular, it 
 must be borne in mind that "on the whole" they are not 
 eligible "to join trade-unions," the latter being confined 
 mainly to skilled crafts. 
 
 There is a tendency among certain theorists to idealize 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , pp. 531 , 541. Jenks 
 and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 191, 206-207. 
 
 * Documentary History of American Industrial Society, vol. viii., 1840- 
 1860. Voice of History, Fitchburg, Massachusetts, Oct. 9, 1845. 
 
 3 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit*, p, 207. 
 
Labor Organizations 347 
 
 the trade-union in the abstract as the economic organization 
 of "the working class." The craft union, as it exists in 
 real life, not in theory, partakes of the nature of the mediae- 
 val guild: its object is to assure work to its members. To 
 accomplish this purpose, it seeks to limit the number of 
 competitors. 1 
 
 To criticise individual union leaders for this attitude is to 
 betray a misconception of the essence of the craft union: 
 its exclusiveness is not an "abuse," it is a policy. To 
 organize "the working class" is not the aim of the trade 
 union. a It strives only to organize as many f ellow-craf ts- 
 
 * The policy of the flint-glass workers' union is thus described in the 
 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 325: "Being a highly 
 skilled trade, it is not troubled by the immigration of unskilled laborers. 
 Those who come to this country are mainly from Norway, Sweden, and 
 Alsace-Lorraine, where they have learned their trade. There are two 
 considerations which restrict the entrance of immigrants. First, the 
 initiation fee imposed by the union. This fee was formerly $100 for 
 foreigners, and $3 for Americans. The fee has been reduced to $50 for 
 foreigners, the American fee remaining at $3. There is an opinion in 
 the union that this extreme discrimination against foreigners is not 
 advantageous, as it compels them to enter non-union shops instead of 
 joining the union. This is known to have been the fact in at least one 
 large non-union establishment manned mainly by foreigners. " In this 
 case discrimination was practised against highly skilled immigrants from 
 Northern and Western Europe, usually classified as "desirable. " 
 
 a The philosophy of trade-unionism is expressed without equivocation 
 in the following quotation from the testimony of Mr. A. A. Roe, repre- 
 senting the railway brotherhoods, before the committee on Immigra- 
 tion and Naturalization: 
 
 ' ' Mr. Roe. I take this position, without any hesitancy at all, that as I 
 see it, the influx displaces the workman of this country, the wage-earner, 
 and causes a competition for his position, increases the number of appli- 
 cants for work. This brought into existence the organizations, drove 
 men together. They had to get into the organizations to give them 
 power to maintain their position, to save the comforts of their homes, 
 and if you say that is a good thing, well and good. 
 
 " Mr. Sabath. It is a good condition: organization is a good con- 
 dition, and if they are responsible for any improvements in the condition 
 of the workingmen, then they are entitled to thanks. 
 
 " Mr. Roe. A better condition would be one that would not require the 
 
348 Immigration and Labor 
 
 men as are necessary to control the trade. There is no place 
 for the unskilled laborer in the trade-union of the prevailing 
 type. There are situations where the interests of the craft 
 union may be antagonistic to organization among the un- 
 skilled, as has been exemplified in the recent Lawrence strike. 
 The United Textile Workers' Union of America, of which 
 Mr. John Golden is president, for many years previous to the 
 strike, had at Lawrence an organization confined to the 
 skilled men in the mills. It was easy for the mill owners to 
 satisfy the demands of the few skilled men, who were but 
 a very small fraction of the whole labor force. They were 
 willing to remain at work. The demands of the thousands 
 of unskilled workers, however, could not be satisfied with- 
 out a greater financial sacrifice than the mill owners were 
 prepared to make. The suspension of work caused by the 
 strike of the immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe 
 and Asia Minor was an injury to the members of the United 
 Textile Workers' Union, who had nothing to gain from the 
 success of the strike. Viewing the controversy not from an 
 altruistic, but from a business point of view, they naturally 
 sided with the mill owners against the strikers, "comforted 
 that the whirligig of time was bringing them around as bul- 
 warks of conservatism even in the eyes of the employers." 1 
 This diversity of economic interests of the aristocracy of 
 skilled labor and of the masses of unskilled men, women, and 
 children accounts for the fact that "the English-speaking 
 labor men have not been urged by such a missionary zeal 
 toward the recent immigrants as should have been theirs 
 on human grounds no more than on the basis of sound associ- 
 ation among the whole labor force." 2 
 
 organization; would not make the organization necessary. A better 
 condition would be one where hours , conditions of employment, and wages 
 were such that organization of labor for these purposes was unnecessary," 
 Hearings before the Commission on Immigration and Naturalization, 
 House of Representatives, Sixty-first Congress, p. 256. 
 
 1 Robert A. Woods: "The Clod Stirs," The Survey, March 16, 1912, 
 pp. 1930-1931. *Ibid. 
 
Labor Organizations 349 
 
 Discussing the possibilities of organization among the 
 unskilled, a student of organized labor says: 
 
 The immigrant is usually accustomed to some form of social organi- 
 zation. He is not as individualistic as is the typical American. He can 
 be organized with others into labor unions; and when the unskilled 
 immigrants from a variety of birthplaces are thus associated, the result- 
 ing union is usually strong, coherent, and easily directed by capable and 
 enthusiastic leaders. The McKees Rocks strike furnishes an excellent 
 illustration of the solidarity of the unskilled when organized. x 
 
 On the home training of Italian immigrants in organi- 
 zation the report of the Immigration Commission contains 
 interesting material, which unfortunately has been disre- 
 garded in its conclusions. 
 
 In recent years the labor-union movement has grown rapidly and to 
 large proportions among the industrial as well as the agricultural workers 
 of Italy, and it is said that the activities of the unions have helped to 
 advance wages in both fields. In 1907, according to Annuario Statis- 
 tico for 1905-1907, there were 2950 industrial unions in the Kingdom, 
 with a total of 362,533 members. From 1901 to 1904, inclusive, there 
 were 3032 industrial strikes, involving 621,737 workers, and in the 
 various years from 63 to 80 per cent of the strikes were reported as 
 "successful" or "partly successful." 11 
 
 The most noteworthy feature of this movement is the 
 progress of organization among farm hands, which has no 
 counterpart in the United States. The statistics presented 
 in Table 105 show that even the despised South Italian farm 
 laborer is capable of organization and concerted action. 
 
 On the labor movement in Russia, a compilation of 
 statistics from Russian official sources has been published 
 by the United States Bureau of Labor. 
 
 Previous to the revolution of 1905, labor organizations 
 and strikes were treated as conspiracies in Russia. During 
 the revolution the severity of the law was relaxed for a 
 short time, but with the suppression of the revolution the 
 old repressive policy was resumed. Thus the only oppor- 
 
 1 Carlton: loc. tit., pp. 346-347. 
 
 a Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4 (in press). 
 
350 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 105. 
 
 AGRICULTURAL LABOR UNIONS AND STRIKES AMONG AGRICULTURAL 
 LABORERS IN ITALY. 1 
 
 Geographical 
 division 
 
 Local unions, 1901 
 
 Strikes, 1901 to 1904 inclusive 
 
 Number 
 
 Membership 
 
 Number 
 
 Participants ' 
 
 Northern Italy 
 The rest of the 
 Kingdom 
 
 28 9 
 1014 
 
 49,884 
 229,629 
 
 701 
 
 404 
 
 171,911 
 315,229 
 
 Total 
 
 1303 
 
 278,513 
 
 iios 3 
 
 487,140 
 
 
 tunity the wage-warners of the Russian Empire had to show 
 their capacity for organization and concerted action was in 
 1905. According to the statistics published by the Russian 
 government, the total number of strikers in factories and 
 mines during the year 1905 was 2,915,000. This figure does 
 not include the railways and the postal-telegraph service, 
 which were completely paralyzed by the strikes of I9O5. 3 
 According to the census of 1897, the total number of 
 railroad employees, exclusive of administrative officials, 
 was 682,000 and the total number of employees in the 
 postal-telegraph service, exclusive of higher officials, was 
 75,000. 4 The total number of strikers for the year 1905 
 may therefore be conservatively estimated at 3,672,000. 
 The highest number of strikers recorded in the United 
 States for any one year between 1881 and 1905 was 533,000, 
 in 1 902 . 5 The strikes in the factories of the Russian Empire 
 in 1905 affected 32.6 per cent of all establishments under 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, Table 17 (condensed). 
 
 a Of the 1105 strikes among agricultural laborers a large majority 
 were reported as successful or partly successful. 
 
 3 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 86: I. M. Rubinow, Foreign 
 Statistical Publications, Russia, p. 284. _ 
 
 Premier Recensement Central de la Population de I' Empire de Russie t 
 1897, vol. ii., pp. II, 250-251. 
 
 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1909, p. 240. 
 
Labor Organizations 351 
 
 factory inspection, comprising 60 per cent of all wage- 
 earners. x 
 
 The strikes in the Russian Empire drew together wage- 
 earners of all those nationalities which make up the bulk 
 of our immigration from Russia : Hebrews, Poles, Lithuan- 
 ians, Russians, and Ruthenians (South Russians). 
 
 It is evident that a good many of the immigrants from 
 Russia, Poland, and Italy bring with them an understand- 
 ing of the aims of organized labor. These immigrants serve 
 as a nucleus of organization among their countrymen. 2 This 
 fact has been brought to the attention of the American 
 public in the recent strikes of the garment workers and 
 textile mill operatives. 
 
 From all available data it is clear that if organized labor 
 in the United States has not succeeded in welding together 
 a majority of the wage-earners and in securing for them a 
 greater share of the prosperity of the country, the fault is 
 not with immigration in general, nor with immigration from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe in particular. Race pre- 
 judice, which the coming of the immigrant has increased 
 among the English-speaking workers is considered by some 
 writers among the contributory causes which have retarded 
 the development of unionism in this country. 3 The pri- 
 mary cause, however, is the substitution of machinery for 
 human skill, which is taking the ground from the craft union. 
 Since the unskilled labor which has superseded the labor of 
 the skilled mechanic is performed by recent immigrants, the 
 breakdown of the old organization is conceived by the trade- 
 unionist as the effect of recent immigration. This view is 
 given expression in the following statement : 
 
 In the occupations and industries in which the pressure of the com- 
 petition of the recent immigrant has been directly felt, either because 
 
 1 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 86, pp. 271-272. 
 
 a Since these lines were written (in 1912) the revolution in Russia and 
 the great strikes of 1920 in Italy have made labor a dominant force in 
 the economic and political life of those countries. 
 
 3 Carlton, loc. cit., p. 63. 
 
352 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the nature of the work was such as to permit of the immediate em- 
 ployment of the immigrant or through the invention of improved 
 machinery his employment was made possible in occupations which 
 formerly required training and apprenticeship, the labor organizations 
 have been, in a great many cases, completely overwhelmed and 
 disrupted. 1 
 
 Where the invention of improved machinery has dis- 
 pensed with the necessity of training and apprenticeship.it is 
 plain that labor organizations which were built upon special 
 training and apprenticeship were doomed to die a natural 
 death for want of supporters. Could a union of blacksmiths 
 be maintained in a modern foundry where steam hammers 
 are used? With the occupation of the blacksmith gone, his 
 union must inevitably have been "disrupted" even in a 
 purely American community without a single immigrant 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 
 Another obstacle to the progress of trade-unionism is that 
 the principal industries to-day are controlled by combina- 
 tions, which have reduced competition among employers 
 of labor to a minimum. A trust can afford to hold out in a 
 strike as long as it chooses, since it can shift its losses to the 
 consumers. The workmen, on the contrary, cannot strike 
 without end. As a result, "the unions have practically 
 disappeared from the trusts, and are disappearing from the 
 large corporations." 8 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. tit., p. 192. 
 
 a Prof. Commons in the American Journal of Sociology, vol. xiii., 
 (1908), p. 759. 
 
CHAPTER XVI 
 
 PAUPERISM AND CRIME 
 
 A. Introductory 
 
 preceding review of comparative statistics and de- 
 1 scriptive history of labor conditions in the past and 
 present has disclosed no evidence in support of the view that 
 the economic interests of the wage-earner have suffered in 
 consequence of immigration. But it is claimed that the 
 evil effects of immigration show themselves in an alarming 
 increase of pauperism and crime. The statistics of depend- 
 ency and delinquency, however, give no occasion for alarm. 
 According to an investigation made by the Bureau of Immi- 
 gration, the total number of inmates of penal institutions, 
 insane asylums, and almshouses in 1908 was 610,477, x which 
 included native and naturalized citizens and aliens. The 
 enumeration of the same classes by the Bureau of the 
 Census in 1904 gave their number as 634,877. 2 A compari- 
 son of these figures clearly shows that the large immigration 
 of the five-year period 1903-1908 was accompanied by an 
 actual decrease of pauperism and crime. 
 
 Whether or not the number of paupers in charitable insti- 
 tutions can " serve as a general index of prevailing distress/' 3 
 is beside the question: the contention is that pauperism is 
 
 1 Report of the Commissioner -General of Immigration, 1908, p. 96. 
 
 * Benevolent Institutions, p. 12. Paupers in Almshouses, p. 6. 
 Insane and Feeble-minded in Hospitals and Institutions, pp.6, 107. 
 Prisoners and Juvenile Delinquents, pp. 14, 228. 
 
 * Paupers in Almhouses, p. 8. 
 
 353 
 
354 Immigration and Labor 
 
 on the increase, whereas the latest statistics show that the 
 millions of recent immigrants imposed no new burdens upon 
 the charitable and penal institutions of the country. 
 
 B. Pauperism 
 
 The Immigration Commission, in its conclusions, notes a 
 decrease of pauperism among immigrants of the present day, 
 compared with the past. 
 
 The number of those admitted who receive assistance from organized 
 charity in cities is relatively small. In the Commission's investigation 
 which covered the activities of the associated charities in 43 cities, in- 
 cluding practically all the larger immigrant centers except New York, 
 it was found that a small percentage of the cases represented immigrants 
 who had been in the United States three years or under, while nearly 
 half of all the foreign-born cases were those who had been in the United 
 States twenty years or more. This investigation was conducted during 
 the winter of 1908-09 before industrial activities had been fully resumed 
 following the financial depression of 1907-8, and this inquiry showed 
 that the recent immigrants, even in cities in times of relative industrial 
 inactivity, did not seek charitable assistance in any considerable 
 numbers. 1 
 
 The records of the charitable institutions of New York 
 City also show that the recent immigrant races furnish a 
 much smaller relative number of applicants for charity than 
 the old immigrant races. Table 106 gives the nativity of 
 lodgers who were sheltered in the Municipal Lodging House 
 in New York City during the first quarter of the year 1908, 
 when the crisis was in its acutest stage. 
 
 The immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe fur- 
 nished less than their proporti on of homeless men even in 
 a period of industrial depression. The population tables of the 
 XIII. Census for New York City are not as detailed as those 
 of the XII. Census. It may be inferred, however, from the 
 published figures that the ratio of pauperism relative to 
 population must have been still more favorable to the races 
 of Southern and Eastern Europe thaif shown in Table 106. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 36. 
 
Pauperism and Crime 
 
 TABLE 1 06. 
 
 355 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION, BY NATIVITY, OF LODGERS AT MUNICIPAL 
 LODGING HOUSE IN NEW YORK CITY DURING JANUARY, FEBRUARY, 
 AND MARCH, 1908, AND OF THE MALE POPULATION 21 YEARS OF AGB 
 AND OVER AT THE XII. CENSUS. * 
 
 Nativity 
 
 Lodgers 
 1908 
 
 Males of 
 full age, 
 1900 
 
 Total 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 English-speaking : 
 United States 
 
 46.2 
 
 4.C 7 
 
 Ireland 
 
 21. 1 
 
 IO.Q 
 
 England, Scotland, and Wales 
 
 6.0 
 
 4.1 
 
 Germany 
 
 Q.5 
 
 15-1 
 
 Scandinavian 
 
 I 7 
 
 2 O 
 
 France 
 
 o s 
 
 o 6 
 
 Russia 
 
 4.O 
 
 5.8 
 
 Austria 
 
 2. 1 
 
 2.8 
 
 Italy 
 
 1 .4 
 
 6.3 
 
 
 64 
 
 63 
 
 English-speaking 
 
 74 2 
 
 60.7 
 
 All others 
 
 '* m 
 
 2 s *. 8 
 
 JQ.-l 
 
 Native 
 
 46.2 
 
 45.7 
 
 Foreign-born 
 
 n 
 
 51.8 
 
 54. 1 
 
 Northern and Western Europe 
 
 JQ. 7 
 
 12. Q 
 
 Eastern and Southern Europe. . 
 
 7 7 
 
 14.0 
 
 Other countries 
 
 6 4 
 
 . 6.3 
 
 
 
 
 The increase of the Russian population of New York 
 City in 1900-1910 was 168 per cent, which raised it to 10.3 
 per cent of the total population of the city; the proportion 
 of adult males in a national group comprising many recent 
 immigrants must necessarily have increased at a greater 
 rate. The increase of the Italians amounted to 134 per 
 cent, and that of the Austrians to 1 10 per cent. 2 
 
 It might be argued that the higher ratio of dependency 
 
 1 Report of the Commission of Immigration of the State of New York, 
 p. 201. XII. Census. Population, Part I., Table 83, pp, 938-945; 
 Table 80, pp. 930-931. 
 
 2 XIII, Census. Population, vol. i., pp. 178^ 826-827, 
 
356 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 among the Irish is the result of their "displacement by the 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans. ' ' It was shown, however, 
 by the Industrial Commission that in pauperism the Irish 
 had always been in the lead. The demonstration of this 
 fact is given in Table 107, which shows that in 1885-1895, 
 when the Italians and Hebrews from Russia and Austria 
 were but a small fraction of the population of New York 
 City, and even as far back as 1854-1860, when there were 
 practically none at all, the preponderance of the Irish among 
 the recipients of charity was as great as in more recent years. 
 
 TABLE 107. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION, BY NATIVITY, OF FOREIGN-BORN RECIPIENTS 
 
 OF CHARITY, 1854-1860, AND 1885-1895, AND OF THE POPULATION 
 
 OF NEW YORK CITY, 1855 AND 1 890.' 
 
 Country of birth 
 
 Popula- 
 tion 1855 
 
 Relief 
 
 granted 
 1854-1860 
 
 Popula- 
 tion 1890 
 
 Alms- 
 house 
 paupers 
 1885-1895 
 
 Total for all nativities 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 IOO O 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Ireland. 
 
 27 O 
 
 60 o 
 
 12 6 
 
 60 4 
 
 England, Scotland, and Wales. . 
 Germany. 
 
 5-1 
 
 IS 2 
 
 4.5 
 n>.8 
 
 3-1 
 14. O 
 
 6.6 
 
 14. O 
 
 Italy 
 
 
 
 2.6 
 
 O 7 
 
 Russia and Austria-Hungary 
 (Hebrews) 
 
 
 
 a O 
 
 O.O 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 The proportion of English and Irish paupers in Boston in 
 the '30*8 and '40*8 was about the same as in New York City 
 half a century later: 
 
 TABLE 108. 
 
 COMPARATIVE PERCENTAGE OF ENGLISH AND IRISH PAUPERS IN BOSTON, 
 1837-1845, AND IN NEW YORK CITY, 1885-1895.' 
 
 In Boston 
 
 In New York City 
 
 1837-1840 6l . 7 
 
 1841-1845 59-2 
 
 1885-1895 64.8 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. 460, 480. 
 * Census of Boston, 1845, PP- no-ill. Report of the Industrial 
 Commission, vol. xv., p. 480. 
 
Pauperism and Crime 
 
 357 
 
 It is evident from the preceding figures that recent immi- 
 gration is not responsible for the high percentage of pauper- 
 ism among the old English-speaking immigrants. Dr. 
 Kate H. Claghorn, after an exhaustive statistical study of 
 immigration in its relation to pauperism, comes to the 
 conclusion that pauperism " is the result of a considerable 
 period of life and experiences here." It is not the able- 
 bodied workmen and their families, but the industrial 
 invalids that make up the lists of applicants for charity. * 
 
 Unemployment is responsible for but a minority of the 
 cases of pauperism, as appears from Table 109, based upon 
 a classification of 7225 Charity Organization Society cases 
 in New York City: 
 
 TABLE 109. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF CHARITY CASES IN NEW YORK CITY, BY 
 NATIVITY AND CAUSES OF NEED (YEAR). 3 
 
 
 Per cent of 
 
 total for each 
 
 nationality 
 
 Nativity 
 
 Unem- 
 ployment 
 
 Other mis- 
 fortune 
 
 All other 
 causes 
 
 American 
 
 24. 57 
 
 44 27 
 
 *i 16 
 
 English 
 
 24.68 
 
 4.^ .4-7 
 
 ?i.85 
 
 Irish 
 
 18.87 
 
 47. -IQ 
 
 a-i.74 
 
 German. 
 
 28 62 
 
 SO 66 
 
 20. 72 
 
 Italian 
 
 <iO 85 
 
 47.66 
 
 21 4Q 
 
 Russian and Polish ... 
 
 
 2-1.87 
 
 61.26 
 
 14.87 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 " The census of 1890 showed that 92 per cent of the foreign-born male 
 almshouse paupers had been in this country ten years or more. . . Over- 
 work, poor food, and life in the airless, sunless, and crowded tenements 
 of the city, or in the equally crowded and even more unsanitary dwell- 
 ings of the mill or the mining town the conditions accompanying the 
 early stages of the immigrant's progress tend strongly to break down 
 the physical health of the sturdy Italian or Austrian peasants, or even 
 of the Jews, more accustomed to the unsanitary conditions of city life." 
 Kate H. Claghorn : Immigration in its Relation to Pauperism. Annals 
 of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, July, 1904, pp. 
 187-200. 3 Ibid., p. 199. 
 
358 Immigration and Labor 
 
 C. Crime 
 
 One of the favorite arguments against immigration since 
 the days of the Know-Nothings has been the assertion that 
 "the foreigner in proportion to his numbers furnishes by far 
 the greater part of crime. " x In the middle of the nineteenth 
 century the Irish immigrant was the object of popular odium 
 as Tsi of a potential criminal. 2 Fifty years later the 
 suspicion turned upon "the undesirable immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. ' ' Although the latest statis- 
 tics of prisoners, published by the Bureau of the Census 
 simultaneously with the creation of the Immigration Com- 
 mission, showed "that the popular belief that the foreign- 
 born are filling the prisons has little foundation in fact," 3 
 yet the Immigration Commission approached the subject 
 under the influence of the popular prejudice. In its report 
 on Emigration Conditions in Europe the Commission 
 lends its support to "the not unfounded belief that certain 
 kinds of criminality are inherent in the Italian race." 
 Accompanying this inherent criminal tendency, in the opin- 
 ion of the Commission, "is also a seemingly inherent ability 
 to avoid arrest and conviction. " The evidence in support 
 of this indictment of the whole Italian race is merely cir- 
 cumstiitial. There has been a ' ' remarkable decrease in the 
 number of murders and homicides in Italy," and, it is alleged, 
 there has been a "startling growth of Italian criminality of 
 the same nature in the United States. " Although it " obvi- 
 ously cannot be mathematically determined" . . . "to what 
 extent emigration is responsible for the decrease of crime in 
 
 1 Sydney G. Fisher: " Immigration and Crime," Popular Science 
 Monthly, September, 1896, p. 625. 
 
 a " The newspapers and pamphlets of that time published statistics 
 which showed that, although the foreign population was only an eighth 
 of the whole, yet it furnished . . . 1000 more criminals than all the re- 
 maining seven eighths of the people. . . - Every one-hundred and fifty- 
 four of them produced a criminal." Ibidr- These early statistics were 
 discredited by later criticism. Cf. Roland P. Falkner: Statistics of 
 Crime in United States. Prisoners, 1904, p. 41. 
 
Pauperism and Crime 359 
 
 Italy," yet "in view of the fact that the decrease has been 
 coincident with the emigration movement, and also with 
 the" supposed "growth of Italian criminality in the United 
 States, it is impossible to avoid the conclusion that these 
 ... results . . . had been due in large part to the emigra- 
 tion to this country of criminals and the criminallyinclined." 
 The Commission concedes that "there are of course other 
 elements which should be taken into consideration, such as 
 the advance of civilization and the better enforcement of 
 law in parts of Italy, " but these considerations are of little 
 weight. To be sure, according to Italian statistics of crime, 
 "Sicily, which has a large emigration, and Liguria, which has 
 much the smallest emigration in proportion to population, 
 show nearly the same per cent of decrease," in murders and 
 homicides. But these facts are of no consequence. The 
 homicidal tendency of the Italian immigrant is proved, on 
 the one hand, by the fact that in certain provinces which 
 "furnish the greatest number of transoceanic emigrants 
 according to the population, there has been an exceptionally 
 large decrease in the number of murders and homicides com- 
 mitted," and, on the other hand, by the fact, "that the 
 prevalence of murder and homicide is as a rule much greater 
 in Compartimenti which furnish the largest number of trans- 
 oceanic emigrants, and consequently are the source of the 
 greater part of the Italian movement to the United States." x 
 
 This criminological theory is significant in so far only as 
 it betrays the bias of the Commission against the immigrant. 
 Yet, notwithstanding its strong prejudice, which no evidence 
 could overcome, the results of its investigation prove to the 
 satisfaction of its own interpreters, that, "undue significance 
 has been attached" to the supposed effects of immigration 
 upon criminality. 
 
 "The number of . . . criminals arriving . . . taken as a 
 percentage of the whole coming is so small that little heed 
 need be paid to it. " 
 
 "Although available statistical material is too small to 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 4, pp. 204, 205, 209. 
 
360 Immigration and Labor 
 
 draw positive conclusions, such material as is available 
 would indicate that immigrants are no more inclined toward 
 criminality on the whole than are native Americans." 
 
 "It is impossible to produce satisfactory evidence that 
 immigration has resulted in an increase of crime out of pro- 
 portion to the increase in the adult population." 1 
 
 The State of New York, which is more affected by immi- 
 gration than any other State in the Union, has compiled 
 annual statistics of crime commencing with the year 1830. 
 The results of an analysis of these statistics, by the writer, 
 are briefly summed up in the following paragraphs. 2 
 
 Surveying the general trend for the seventy-five year 
 period 1830-1905, we find that the increase of crime has 
 merely kept pace with the growth of population. The 
 relative rate of criminality in 1890 was the same as in 1840, 
 notwithstanding the change in the racial composition of the 
 population of the State. In the year 1900 there was just 
 one more conviction for every 100,000 of the population than 
 in 1890, and in 1905 four convictions per 100,000 people in 
 excess of 1900. The fluctuations of the movement of popu- 
 lation and of the rate of criminality indicate that the causes 
 which are favorable to the growth of population tend to 
 reduce crime, and vice versa, the causes which retard the 
 growth of population are productive of an increase of crime. 
 
 The effects of immigration upon criminality can be traced 
 from 1850 when the census inquiries for the first time took 
 notice of nativity. The statistics for the half-century 
 following show that an increase of the percentage of the for- 
 eign-born population is accompanied by a decrease of crim- 
 inality, and vice versa. During the latest ten-year period, 
 1900-1909, the wave of criminality rose when immigration 
 was at its lowest ebb, while the high-tide of immigration was 
 contemporaneous with a decrease of crime. 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. /., pp. 51, 52, 65. 
 
 a For a detailed statistical analysis of -the data upon which these 
 conclusions are based, the reader is referred to an article by the 
 present writer on "Immigration and Crime," in The American Journal 
 of Sociology, January, 1912. 
 
Pauperism and Crime 361 
 
 Thus it is found that in the social profit-and-loss account, 
 crime and immigration figure on the opposite sides of the 
 ledger. Immigration does not impair the worker's oppor- 
 tunities to earn a living; on the contrary increase of immi- 
 gration goes parallel with increase of business prosperity 
 and decrease of crime. 
 
PART IIL 
 
 IMMIGRANTS IN THE LEADING INDUSTRIES 
 
 [The Immigration Commission has devoted several volumes of its 
 report to a description of labor conditions in special industries which 
 are generally believed to typify the evils of recent immigration. Of 
 these, five will be considered in this part.] 
 
 CHAPTER XVII 
 
 THE GARMENT WORKERS 
 
 THE manufacture of clothing in the United States is an 
 immigrant industry. Immigrants have furnished 
 the labor and in most instances the capital. 1 The labor 
 conditions in this industry have attracted wide public 
 attention by frequent strikes, ever since the Russian Jews 
 have become thepredominant element among the operatives. 
 The clothing industry has become associated in the public 
 mind with the sweating system, and since the employees are, 
 with few exceptions, immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, the conclusion is readily reached that the root of 
 the sweating system is in the character of the new immigra- 
 tion. This view draws support from the attitude of the 
 United Garment Workers of America, an organization of 
 Jewish garment workers, which, at its annual convention 
 in 1905, adopted a resolution demanding restriction of 
 further immigration for the protection of the foreign-born 
 workers already here. 2 And yet a dispassionate study of 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Committee, vol. 1 1, p. 417. 
 1 John R. Commons, Races and Immigrants in America, p. 115. 
 
 362 
 
The Garment Workers 363 
 
 the clothing industry shows that labor conditions have very 
 substantially improved with the coming of the "new 
 immigration. " 
 
 The sweating system did not originate with the Jewish 
 clothing workers: it preceded them by more than half a 
 century. In the Report of Woman and Child Wage- 
 Earners in the United States, recently published by the 
 United States Bureau of Labor, we find a vast amount of 
 information on the employment of women in the clothing 
 industry in the first third of the nineteenth century, at the 
 time when the wage-earners were nearly all American-born. 
 
 The history of this period, like that of the better-known period of the 
 machine, is a tale of long hours, low wages, and exploitation. The 
 "sweating system," indeed, in the broad sense of that term, was es- 
 tablished in this country at the very beginning of the ready-made 
 garment business and has developed simultaneously with that business. 
 The contract system established stages and degrees of sweating, but a 
 study of the sweating system would have to extend back at least as 
 far as the beginning, in 1828, of Matthew Carey's agitation in the in- 
 terests of ... the working women, of whom he estimated that there 
 were in Philadelphia, New York, Boston, and Baltimore between 18,000 
 and 20,000. . . . The disclosures made by Matthew Carey during 
 the course of his investigation and agitation in behalf of the sewing 
 women seem, though quaintly worded, very modern in their substance. 
 It was set forth, for example, in the resolutions passed at a meeting in 
 Philadelphia on February 21, 1829, that "it requires great expertness, 
 unceasing industry from sunrise till 10 or n o'clock at night, constant 
 employment (which very few of them have) without any interruption 
 whatever from sickness, or attention to their families, to earn a dollar 
 and a half a week, and, in many cases, a half or a third of their time is 
 expended in attending their children, and no small portion in traveling 
 eight, ten or fourteen squares for work, and as many to take it back 
 when finished." . . . The committee appointed at this meeting re- 
 ported: "That . . . the wages paid to seamstresses who work in their 
 own apartments to spoolers, to spinners, to folders of printed books 
 and in many cases to those who take in washing, are utterly inadequate 
 to their support, even if fully employed . . . whereas the work is so pre- 
 carious that they are often unemployed sometimes for a whole week 
 together, and very frequently one or two days in each week." 1 
 
 1 Helen L. Sumner: "History of Women in Industries of the United 
 
364 Immigration and Labor 
 
 In Boston (in 1830) the average weekly wages of a woman garment 
 worker, when fully employed, were given by a contemporary writer as 
 but a dollar or a dollar and a quarter, while the common rent of a room 
 was a dollar a week. 1 
 
 In other words, the weekly wages of a Boston working 
 woman were barely sufficient to provide for rent. While 
 fully employed, she was not self-supporting, but had to 
 depend upon her family for the necessities of life. 
 
 In Baltimore, too, in 1833, the wages of sewing women were declared 
 not sufficient for the genteel support of the single individual who 
 performs the work, although she may use every effort of industry which 
 her constitution is capable of sustaining. 3 
 
 Instances of the sweating system are again recorded in 
 1844, still before the first inrush of Irish immigration. It 
 was reported 
 
 that a man and two women working together from twelve to sixteen 
 hours a day earned a dollar amongst them, and that the women, if 
 they did not belong to the family, received each about $1.25 a week for 
 their work, the man paying out of the remaining $3.50 about $1.00 a 
 week for rent of his garret. * 
 
 From 1850, the Irish workers became predominant in the 
 clothing industry. At that period the clothing industry in 
 New York City was in its infancy. There were no factories, 
 and the workers occupied small rooms or sweatshops. 4 
 
 In 1853 the investigation of the clothing trade made by the New 
 York Tribune disclosed the existence of a "middle system." For 
 example, near one of the streets running from the Bowery to the East 
 River an old Irish woman was found who had four girls at work for 
 her, their compensation consisting solely of food for six days of the week. 
 In another case a woman had hired four "learners," two of whom re- 
 ceived only board and lodging, and the other two $1.00 a week each 
 without food.* 
 
 States." Report of Woman and Child Wage-Eat ners in the United States, 
 vol. ix., pp. 123-124. Ibid., p. 125. * Ibid., p. 126. 
 
 } Ibid., p. 141. 
 
 < Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. II, p. 369. 
 
 5 Sumner,/oc. cit., pp. 141-142. 
 
The Garment Workers 365 
 
 According to the Immigration Commission, the "displace- 
 ment of the old races by the new, or recent, immigrants" 
 has been "one resulting through the willingness of the 
 'raw* immigrants to accept lower wages than those who 
 have been in this country for a longer period of time. " x 
 Yet when the earnings of the "raw" immigrant women of 
 the present day are compared with those of the " old races, " 
 it is found that the native American and the Irish working 
 women of past generations were "willing" to work only for 
 board and lodging, or even for board alone, depending 
 upon their families for other necessities, whereas the Jewish 
 factory girls are at least self-supporting. The question is 
 not whether wages to-day are all that could be desired, but 
 whether they have been reduced by recent immigration, 
 and Dr. Sumner's historical research proves the contrary. 
 One of the chief factors which kept down the wages of 
 working women in the early history of the clothing industry 
 was country competition. 
 
 " We know instances," said the New York Morning News, in 1845, 
 " where shirtwaist makers put their work out in the country in the 
 winter at II cents each. The work is done by those who do not make 
 it a means of living, but use it merely as an auxiliary to dress." The 
 Voice of Industry too, stated in 1845 that "a gentleman told us, the other 
 day, that he saw the daughter of a respectable farmer making shirts at 
 II cents apiece, for one of the dealers. He asked her whether she 
 thought it a sufficient price. "No,' said she, ' if I were obliged to 
 support myself, I could not do it by this work; but I merely employ 
 my time which otherwise I should not use. ' " 
 
 In the same year the chairwoman of a meeting of working women 
 in New York said that she knew several employers who paid only from 
 IO to 18 cents per day, and that one employer, who offered girls 20 
 cents per day, told them that if they did not take it "he would obtain 
 girls from Connecticut who would work for less even than what he 
 offered." 
 
 By 1850, the cheap labor of the farmhouse is said to have been em- 
 ployed " in the getting up of clothing, skirts, stocks, hosiery, suspen- 
 ders, carriage trappings, buttons, and a hundred other light things." 8 
 
 x Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 11., p. 369. 
 * Stunner, loc. cit., pp. 140-141. 
 
366 Immigration and Labor 
 
 These conditions have changed as the direct result of 
 immigration. The rapid growth of the t^age- working 
 population created a market for ready-made clothing. 
 
 These new branches of work, whereby a product, which when for- 
 merly made by the custom tailor, the dressmaker, or the housewife cost 
 higher prices than most of the people could afford, is now made in the 
 latest styles, enable all classes of people to be better dressed and to 
 spend much more money every year for clothing. Herein the immigrant 
 * has created his own employment. x 
 
 The expansion of the clothing industry was made possible 
 by the introduction of the factory system with its greater 
 efficiency than home work. The operation of a factory 
 requires a regular force of employees whose livelihood must 
 be provided for by their wages. This is the reason why the 
 immigrant girl from Southern or Eastern Europe cannot 
 accept the low wages which the daughters of native Ameri- 
 can farmers regarded as satisfactory. A development 
 peculiar to the factory method of clothing manufacturing 
 was the substitution of male for female labor, with a 
 consequent increase of the rate of wages. 
 
 The view that the new immigrants tend to lower the 
 wages of the ql^er immigrants apparently finds support in 
 the statistics of the Immigration Commission, which show 
 for each race at present employed in the clothing industry 
 "a general increase in weekly darnings with the increased 
 period of residence. " 2 In other words, the earnings of the 
 
 (recent immigrants are lower than those of the older immi- 
 grants, because, it is explained, "the immigrants of long 
 residence have acquired a higher standard of living and 
 consequently demand a higher wage." 3 Quite naturally 
 then, "the older employees are unable to meet the competi- 
 tion of the recent immigrants, whose demands are not 
 great. " 
 
 The reasoning sounds plausible, still it will not stand close 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. xxvii. 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. n, p. 380. 
 > Ibid., p. 370. 4 Ibid. 
 
The Garment Workers 367 
 
 scrutiny. Indeed, if the fact that the older immigrants 
 "demand a higher wage" be sufficient to secure to them an 
 actual increase in weekly earnings, then there is nothing 
 to prevent them from demanding and securing a higher 
 wage, notwithstanding the competition of the recent immi- 
 grants. If, on the contrary, the older employees are unable 
 to meet the competition of the recent immigrants, then the 
 increased period of residence could not help them to a 
 "general increase in weekly earnings." The fallacy of the 
 Commission's reasoning is due to the fact that it mistakes 
 cause for effect: higher earnings are not the effect, but the 
 cause, of a higher standard of living. Wages in the labor 
 market are not determined by the amount the worker 
 desires to spend, but by the services he is able to render. It 
 is plain that competition would not permit the clothing 
 manufacturer to pay higher wages to an older employee 
 merely as a reward for long residence, if recent immigrants 
 could be hired to do the same work more cheaply. If the 
 older employees are able to command, not merely to "de- 
 mand, " a higher wage, it is evidently because their services 
 are worth more than the "inexperienced labor" of the 
 newcomers. And it is equally evident that th!e immigrants 
 who "must have work on landing in New York, and . . . 
 find their way to the clothing manufactories," 1 do not 
 compete with the older employees for the higher positions 
 requiring experience. 
 
 But it is said that the new immigrants "annually crowd 
 the shops of the city (of New York) in thousands, forcing 
 workers who have preceded them to move up in the scale 
 of occupation or to enter other employment. . . . Some 
 of the displaced workers have opened tailoring or repair 
 shops of their own, others have gone into the shops of 
 custom tailors, and many have entered other lines of work."* 
 In every-day language, the opening of a shop by a former 
 wage- worker is not called "displacement," but advance- 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 1 1, p. 370. 
 *Ibid. 
 
368 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ment. Custom tailoring requires a higher grade of skill 
 than the manufacturing of ready-made clothing. If a 
 clothing worker vacates his place in the factory to accept 
 a better position with a custom tailor and the vacancy is 
 filled by a new immigrant, no one in the trade will conceive 
 the change as "displacement" of the older employee by a 
 new hand. There remain only the undefined "other lines 
 of work," into which the incoming thousands are said to 
 have crowded those of their predecessors whom they could 
 not "force" to move up. A sidelight upon this residue 
 is thrown by the narrative of the history of the clothing 
 industry in Baltimore. The first people employed in the 
 clothing shops of that city were 
 
 the Germans, who entered the country in large numbers immediately 
 after the Civil War. Since that time the Russian Hebrews, Lithuan- 
 ians, Poles, Italians, and Bohemians have settled in the city and found 
 employment in the clothing shops, displacing the Germans in the 
 unskilled occupations, and forcing them up into higher work. It is also 
 noticed that, as the Russian Hebrews and Poles work up into the 
 skilled occupations, the Germans leave the industry and enter new 
 fields. This displacement seems to be self-displacement, as there is work 
 for all more work than there are laborers but the Germans are pro- 
 gressive, and as the new races have engaged in the clothing industry they 
 have risen in the scale of occupations, and in many instances have left 
 the industry and found employment in other skilled trades. 1 
 
 Thus we learn that, at least in Baltimore, those who have 
 left the industry have "found employment in other skilled 
 trades," and that the "displacement" is therefore "self- 
 displacement"; in other words, no displacement at all. 
 Expressed in more exact language, the report of the Com- 
 mission Shows +Vo+ *V ^k>thJT1 industry of Pfl]tJTnnrfi has 
 gsosm jrnore rapidly than thft supply nf Uhnr. The ex- 
 pansion of the industry created new positions for skilled 
 workers; these positions were filled first by Germans, next 
 by Russian Hebrews and Poles. This expansion not being 
 confined to the manufacturing of clothing, other indus- 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 11, p. 411. 
 
The Garment Workers 
 
 369 
 
 tries offered opportunities of which the Germans availed 
 themselves. 
 
 It is reasonable to assume that if there is "more work than 
 there are laborers" in Baltimore, the clothing manufacturers 
 of that city would have sufficient enterprise to import 
 some of the thousands who "crowd the shops" of New York 
 City. The fact is that the expansion of the clothing indus- 
 try in New York has been a great deal faster than in Balti- 
 more, as appears from Table no below. It is therefore 
 quite probable that the relation between the demand for, 
 and supply of, labor in the shops of New York is the same 
 as in Baltimore. 
 
 TABLE no. 
 
 COMPARATIVE GROWTH OF THE VALUE OF THE PRODUCTS OF THB 
 CLOTHING INDUSTRY IN NEW YORK AND BALTIMORE, 1 890-1905. x 
 
 City 
 
 i 
 
 Millions of dollars 
 
 Per cent of increase 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 1905 
 
 1890-1900 
 
 1900-1905 
 
 1890-1905 
 
 New York. . . , 
 Baltimore 
 
 1 
 119 
 
 so 
 
 206 
 20 
 
 306 
 23 
 
 73 
 25 
 
 49 
 IS 
 
 157 
 
 44 
 
 The statistics of the Immigration Commission do not dis-f 
 close any tendency on the part of the new immigrant racesV 
 to accept lower wages than the immigrants of older races. \ 
 (See Table in on page 370.) The percentage of recent 
 German immigrants earning $15 a week or over is much 
 less than the percentage of Hebrews and Russians and about 
 the same as the percentage of Italians with the same aver- 
 age earnings. On the opposite end, the percentage of 
 Germans earning less than $10 a week within the first 
 five years of their residence in the United States is some- 
 what greater than that of Hebrews, Russians, Poles, and 
 
 1 Census Reports, Manufactures, 1905, Part I, Table CLXVIII., 
 p. ccxxxiii. 
 
370 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Bohemians. These figures show that the "new immi- 
 gration" does not underbid the immigrants of the older 
 races. On the other hand, the variation in the earnings of 
 representatives of each race indicates that the rate of wages 
 r is. not determined by racial factors, but depends upon 
 ? the personal qualifications and opportunities of individual 
 \workers. 
 
 TABLE in. 
 
 PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF FOREIGN-BORN ADULT MALE CLOTHING 
 
 WORKERS, 1 8 YEARS OF AGE AND OVER, RESIDING IN THE UNITED 
 
 STATES LESS THAN FIVE YEARS, BY RACE AND WEEKLY EARNINGS . T 
 
 Race 
 
 Under Jio 
 
 $10 to 15 
 
 $15 and over 
 
 Hebrew (not Russian) 
 Hebrew (Russian) 
 
 33-9 
 
 -in. I 
 
 42.2 
 
 -JQ.Q 
 
 23-9 
 21 .O 
 
 
 75. -I 
 
 46.8 
 
 17.9 
 
 
 4O.2 
 
 10.8% 
 
 IO.O 
 
 Italian North 
 
 4.C -i 
 
 45. -i 
 
 0.4 
 
 
 4.O.O 
 
 to -o 
 SI .4 9 
 
 8.6 
 
 Italian, South 
 
 S7.6*> 
 
 -la.o 
 
 8.5 
 
 Polish 
 
 ' f 
 
 VI 4 
 
 54. l3. 
 
 8.5 
 
 Bohemian and Moravian. 
 
 35-5 
 
 ot *<* 
 57 -0\ 
 
 7-5 
 
 The Immigration Commission speaks in general terms of 
 the "availability of cheap woman and child labor of the 
 immigrant households" for locating "men's and women's 
 clothing manufacturing establishments" in certain districts 
 "developed in connection with some of the principal indus- 
 tries of the country." * But the statistics of the Commission 
 show that the earnings of recent immigrant women and 
 children in the clothing industry are higher than those of 
 ( native Americans. Thus, adult Russian Hebrew women 
 averaged $8.09 per week, Polish women, $8.07, North Italian 
 women, $7.54, whereas native women of native American 
 parentage earned only $7.41 per week. The majority of 
 Polish women (55.4 per cent) earned more than $7.50 per 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 1 1, p. 301, Table 35. 
 vol. i, p. 541. 
 
The Garment Workers 371 
 
 week, while the majority of American women of native 
 parentage (57.2 per cent) earned less than that amount. 1 
 The same is true of girls between the ages of 14 and 18. 
 Russian Hebrew girls earned on an average $6.13 per week, 
 other Hebrew girls $6.24, South Italian girls $5.56, Polish 
 girls $5.25, whereas native American girls of native parent- 
 age made only $5.02 per week. Nearly one half (45.9 per 
 cent) of the latter earned less than $5 while only a little 
 over one fourth (27.4 per cent) .of the Russian Hebrew 
 girls earned less than that amount. 2 
 
 Confronted with these facts, Professors Jenks and Lauck_ 
 seek to explain them by the assumption that "the lower 
 earnings of the American women" are due "to their in- 
 ability and disinclination to work such long hours as the v 
 foreign-born females in the case of certain piece-rate occu- 
 pations, as, for example, the clothing industry. 1 ' 3 This 
 explanation, however, is purely a matter of conjecture* 
 since the Immigration Commission has made no inquiries 
 regarding hours of labor in the clothing industry. As 
 shown above, the hours were long in the factories and sweat- 
 shops when the women workers were all Americans, and 
 were reduced with the coming of immigrants. The inquiry 
 of the Industrial Commission concerning the hours of labor 
 in the clothing industry in Pennsylvania brought out the fact 
 that the working hours averaged ten per day alike in the city 
 shops where the employees were Jews and Italians, and in 
 country shops, where none but Americans were employed. 4 
 
 The investigations of the Industrial Commission also 
 disclosed the fact that in the beginning of the twentieth 
 century, as half a century before, the American country ^ 
 workers were willing to work for lower wages than the 
 immigrants in the cities. 
 
 In the country districts of Pennsylvania the garment workers are 
 Americans, some of whom can be further distinguished as "Pennsyl- 
 
 1 Reports of ihe Immigration Commission, vol. n, p. 293, Table 26. 
 
 2 Ibid., p. 298, Table 32. * Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., p. 143. 
 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 725. 
 
372 Immigration and Labor 
 
 vania Dutch." In New Jersey they are Americans and German- 
 Americans ... but there is no evidence of a lower standard of living 
 than among their American neighbors. In spite of this, it is these people 
 and their American co-workers who are accepting a lower rate of wages than 
 the Jews in the city. ' 
 
 The most striking difference between the country and town shops is 
 that the operators in the town shops are invariably men and in the 
 country shops they are women. . . . The women coat operators in 
 the country who get the highest wages paid women receive $5.34, and 
 the city women basters on vests are receiving $6.59. Here we find women 
 in the city engaged in a lower class of work and receiving higher pay than 
 the women in the country who are doing the highest grade of work. 3 
 
 The same difference existed between the wages of men in 
 city and country shops: Jewish pressers in the city averaged 
 $11.38 per week, whereas American pressers in the country 
 earned only $7.62 per week. 3 
 
 Because the native American country workers were 
 willing to accept lower wages than the recent immigrants 
 in the cities, the contractors found it profitable to give more 
 steady employment to country than to city workers. While 
 the latter averaged but twenty-eight working weeks in the 
 year, the former were given forty-four weeks, with the result 
 that their annual earnings at lower rates of wages exceeded 
 the earnings of city workers at higher rates. 4 
 
 What enables the American country workers of Pennsyl- 
 vania to underbid the Jewish garment workers of Philadel- 
 phia is the fact that 
 
 the country home workers are usually simply supplementing other 
 earnings. They are farmers' wives and daughters and those of farm 
 laborers. They make clothing in the intervals of housework and farm 
 work, for most of them help in the haying and harvesting. . . . Where 
 the shop replaces the farming-out system, the employees are drawn 
 from these same farmers' families, and a low standard of wages, in- 
 fluenced by the home earnings, prevails throughout.' 
 
 Another no less important cause of the "low standard 
 of wages" of native American country workers is their 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 730. 
 
 a Ibid., pp. 727-729- 3 Ibid., p. 726. 
 
 Ibid., p. 725. $ Ibid., pp. 727-728. 
 
The Garment Workers 373 
 
 V 
 
 isolation, in consequence of which "they must accept his 
 [the contractor's] rate of payment offered through the 
 driver who delivers the goods. " * The Southern and East- 
 ern European clothing workers in the cities, on the contrary, 
 are comparatively well organized. As shown in Chapter 
 XV the percentage of organized workers among them is 
 above the average for the country. Their capacity for 
 concerted action finds full expression only in strikes which 
 rally around the unions many workers not regularly affiliated 
 with them. The highest per cent of employees joining in 
 strikes in 1887-1905 was found among clothing workers, as 
 shown in Table 112: 
 
 TABLE 112. 
 
 PER CENT OF STRIKING EMPLOYEES IN THE CLOTHING INDUSTRY AND IN 
 ALL INDUSTRIES IN THE UNITED STATES, 1887-1905.* 
 
 Industry 
 
 Male 
 
 Female 
 
 Women's clothing 
 
 86.04. 
 
 62. II 
 
 
 81.84 
 
 4V 06 
 
 All industries 
 
 44. qi 
 
 28. IS 
 
 
 
 
 The strikes were, as a rule, led by organizations. Of the 
 20,559 establishments involved in strikes during the twenty- 
 five year period from 1881 to 1905, in only 355 were the 
 strikes not ordered by labor organizations, the annual 
 averages being 835 and 13 establishments, respectively. 
 The proportion of unorganized strikes among workers on 
 men's clothing was 10 per cent; among workers on women's 
 clothing 1 6 per cent, whereas the average for all industries 
 was 31 percent. 3 
 
 The percentage of thoroughly successful strikes of clothing 
 workers for the period 1881-1905 was much above the average, 
 viz. : the percentage in establishments manufacturing men's 
 
 1 Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 728. 
 
 a Twenty- first Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, pp. 90-91. 
 
 *Ibid., pp. 35-36. 
 
374 Immigration and Labor 
 
 clothing, 75.51, and in establishments manufacturing 
 women 's clothing 66.37, whereas the average for all indus- 
 tries in the United States was only 47.94.' These figures 
 will enable the student to appraise at its true value the 
 conclusion of the Immigration Commission that "as a gen- 
 eral proposition it may be said that all improvement in 
 conditions and increases in rates of pay have been secured 
 in spite of the presence of the recent immigrant." 2 
 
 The strike statistics published by the United States 
 Bureau of Labor permit of a comparison between the recent 
 period beginning with the fiscal year 1895, when the immi- 
 grants from Southern and Eastern Europe for the first 
 time outnumbered all others, and the earlier period from 
 January i, 1881, to June 30, 1894. During the 8o's the 
 principal nationalities employed in the clothing shops were 
 the Germans and the Irish: 3 since 1895 the Jews and the 
 Italians have become the predominating element among the 
 workers. It appears that during the thirteen and a half 
 years previous to the fiscal year 1895 the average annual 
 number of strikers in the clothing industry was 9,094, 
 and during the eleven and a half years following it rose to 
 38,683.' 
 
 This is the unbiased testimony of figures in answer to 
 the sweeping generalizations of the Immigration Commis- 
 sion about the reluctance of the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans "to enter labor disputes involving loss of time," 
 their "ready acceptance of a low wage and existing working 
 conditions" and "willingness seemingly to accept in- 
 definitely without protest certain wages and conditions 
 of employment." 5 
 
 1 Twenty-first Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, pp. 81-82. 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , p. 540. 
 *Ibid., vol. i, pp. 516-517. 
 
 Computed from Annual Reports of the Commissioner of Labor: 
 X., p. 1567; XVI., pp. 15, 34, 355; XXL, p. 16. 
 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission^ vol. i, pp. 530-540. 
 
CHAPTER XVIII 
 
 THE COTTON MILLS 
 
 THE cotton mills furnish a good field for the study of 
 the effects of immigration upon the condition of 
 labor in the United States. According to the investiga- 
 tion of the Immigration Commission, 68.7 per cent of the 
 operatives in the New England States were of foreign birth. 
 The races of the "old immigration" were represented by 
 37.8 percent, and those of the "new immigration" by 30.9 
 per cent. 1 The latter are mostly recent arrivals. In 1900 
 the proportion of immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe and their American-born children varied from 
 3.1 per cent in New Hampshire to 13.2 per cent in Massa- 
 chusetts. 3 
 
 The Immigration Commission has obtained from one of 
 the largest and oldest mill corporations figures showing 
 the movement of wages since 1875.3 The movement may 
 be divided into two periods: (i) from 1875 to 1898 and (2) 
 from 1899 to 1908. The first period, when the cotton-mill 
 operatives were practically all English-speaking, was one 
 of intermittent advances and reductions; on the whole 
 wages remained stationary. The second period, which is 
 marked by the advent of the Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans into the cotton mills, is conspicuous by an unin- 
 terrupted upward movement of wages, which was checked 
 only by the crisis of 1908. Still, even after the reduction 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, Table 7, pp. 14-15. 
 Ibid., Table 19, p. 36. 3 2bid. t p. 291. 
 
 375 
 
376 Immigration and Labor 
 
 made on March 30, 1908, wages remained 15 per cent 
 above the level of 1898. To be sure, the first period was 
 one of falling prices, which enabled the cotton-mill opera- 
 tives to maintain their usual standard of living notwith- 
 standing the ' reductions in wages, whereas, on the other 
 hand, the second period was one of rapidly rising prices 
 which offset the increase in wages. It is therefore possible 
 that the operatives were not better off during the later 
 period of rising wages than during the earlier period. Still, 
 assuming that every cut in wages merely restored the 
 previous relation between earnings and the cost of living, 
 it is plain that these reductions must have caused dissatis- 
 faction among the wage-earners. However, the operatives 
 of the New England cotton mills, all of them of Teutonic 
 and Celtic stock, acquiesced in these reductions. On the 
 other hand, though the advances in 1899-1907 may have 
 been nullified by the rising cost of living, each increase in 
 wages was nevertheless the outcome of successful bargaining 
 by the operatives for better terms of employment. 
 
 Still the question is whether the industrial expansion of 
 the period from 1899 to 1907 might not have enabled the 
 operatives to win more substantial advances had there been 
 no immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe. The 
 only method by which such results could have been accom- 
 plished was organization. 
 
 The more recent immigrant employees from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe and Asia, however, [says the Immigration Commission in its 
 summary volume], have been a constant menace to the labor organi- 
 zations, and have been directly and indirectly instrumental in weakening 
 the unions and threatening their disruption. The divergence in lan- 
 guage and the high degree of illiteracy and ignorance among the recent 
 operatives have made their work of organization among them very 
 difficult and expensive. 1 
 
 This conclusion is at variance with the facts recited 
 in the special report of the Commission on " Cotton 
 goods manufacturing in the North Atlantic States": 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 537. 
 
The Cotton Mills 377 
 
 "Fall River, Mass., is the only distinctly trade-union 
 locality in New England," yet there, as elsewhere, the 
 unions are confined to the skilled occupations, whereas the 
 recent immigrants upon entering the cotton mills "take 
 up unskilled work. . . . Many of them never advance 
 beyond the unskilled work. These occupations are not 
 organized, and the coming of the foreigner there does not 
 concern the textile unions."* In Cohoes, N. Y., likewise, 
 " the unions manifest little interest in the immigrant employees 
 until they have advanced to the occupations controlled by the 
 labor organizations." 2 It is evident that "their work of 
 organization" among the unskilled immigrants could have 
 been neither "difficult" nor "expensive." 
 
 With regard to skilled occupations the Immigration 
 Commission has reached two diametrically opposite con- 
 clusions. In the abstract of the reports on immigrants in 
 manufacturing and mining it maintains that 
 
 the advancement in large numbers of the Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans to weaving, spinning, beaming, and similar occupations has tended 
 to bring them into more direct competition with the Americans and older 
 immigrant employees, and to destroy the advantage which the latter 
 class, who control and direct the unions, formerly possessed. * 
 
 In the special report on cotton goods manufacturing the 
 Commission says, on the contrary, that 
 
 at no time has there been a sharp competition between unionized laborers 
 on the one hand, and unorganized immigrant laborers in large numbers on 
 the other. 
 
 The latter conclusion is supported by the following 
 statements : 
 
 The textile occupations themselves, which are unionized, are protected, 
 by the long time required to attain proficiency, from any sudden or 
 immediate competition of unorganized foreigners. . . . Automatic 
 or improved machinery might change this situation, and the coming of 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, pp. 123, 124. 
 . * Ibid., p, 123. * Ibid., vol. I, p. 538. * Ibid., vol. 10, p. 124. 
 
378 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the immigrant might then be a more serious matter for the unions and 
 might subject them to a disastrous competition from unorganized workers 
 accustomed to a lower standard of living, . . . but that is not the condition 
 at present. ... As regards the attitude of the immigrants toward the 
 unions, when they advance to the skilled, organized occupations, even 
 if they do not join the unions, they do not oppose the organization or cut 
 under the unions 1 wages. ... At the time of strikes the recent immi- 
 grants come into the unions in large numbers. ... In times of strikes 
 these foreigners have stood by the unions, even though previously they 
 may not have been members. 1 
 The recent immigrants have not been used as strike-breakers.* 
 
 The only specific strike described in the report of the 
 Commission took place in Lowell, Mass., 3 in 1903. It is 
 characterized as "the only serious controversy between the 
 cotton manufacturers and the operatives" of that city. 
 The history of that controversy is briefly as follows. The 
 mill owners having refused an increase in wages, the unions 
 declared a strike. The mill owners on the same day re- 
 sponded by a lockout. While the mills remained closed, 
 pro-union meetings were held among the Greeks, the Poles, 
 and the Portuguese, and organizations were formed among 
 them. "At the commencement of the agitation for a ten 
 per cent increase in wages, the membership of the unions 
 constituted but a small fraction of the employees in the 
 mills; gradually, however, this membership increased as the 
 strike sentiment grew.*' The unions were defeated, how- 
 ever, by an unexpected turn in the cotton market. 
 
 The price of raw cotton began to rise to such an extent that the manu- 
 facturers who had provided themselves with the necessary supply in 
 advance were able to sell at a considerable profit. One mill actually 
 declared a 4 per cent dividend, on the basis of raw cotton sold at a good 
 advance, due to the high prices during the strike. In this way it would 
 have been possible for them to minimize, or even neutralize entirely 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, pp. 124, 125. 
 
 'Ibid., vol. i, p. 538. 
 
 For some unknown reasons, the name-of the city is hidden under the 
 designation of "Community A." The disguise is betrayed, however, 
 in Table 125 on p. 232, which is a reproduction of Table 24 on p. 45, 
 where Lowell, Mass., is named. 
 
The Cotton Mills 379 
 
 the loss occasioned by the idleness of their plants caused by the strike. 
 It thus became a matter of indifference to them whether work was 
 resumed or not. When this situation generally became known the 
 strike was doomed. 1 
 
 After a suspension of work lasting nine weeks the manu- 
 facturers reopened the mills. From one third , to two thirds 
 of the locked-out operatives returned to the mills on the 
 first day. The ranks of the strikers began to weaken, and 
 after staying out for three weeks the unions unanimously 
 voted to call the strike off. a 
 
 To form a fair judgment of the endurance shown by the 
 Lowell strikers, the length of time they stayed out must be 
 compared with the average duration of strikes in the cotton 
 mills of Massachusetts. The races of Southern and Eastern 
 Europe in 1909 supplied 34 per cent of the total number of 
 operatives in the Lowell cotton mills. 3 In the State at 
 large the proportion of immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe and Asia among the mill operatives of the 
 State varied as follows : 
 
 TABLE 113. 
 
 PERCENTAGE OF IMMIGRANTS FROM SOUTHERN AND EASTERN EUROPE 
 AMONG THE TEXTILE MILL OPERATIVES OF MASSACHUSETTS, l88O- 
 
 IQOO.* 
 
 Mills 
 
 , " Year 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Cotton (immigrants and their children). . . . 
 Textile (immigrants only) 
 
 1900 
 1890 
 1880 
 
 13-2 
 2-3 
 05 
 
 
 The average duration of strikes in the cotton mills of 
 Massachusetts for the twenty-year period from 1881 to 
 1900 was only thirty-six days. 5 Thus the length of time 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, voL I, pp. 292, 293. 
 
 1 Ibid. J Ibid., Table 130, p. 237. 
 
 Ibid., Tables 14, 17, and 19. 
 
 * Sixteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table 3, p. 216. 
 
380 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the Lowell strikers stayed out in 1903 was three quarters 
 in excess of the average for the period when nearly all the 
 operatives were of the English-speaking races. Going 
 over the annals of the strikes in the cotton mills of Massa- 
 chusetts from 1881-1890, when there were scarcely any 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe and Asia 
 among the operatives, we find only one strike that can 
 compare in extent with the Lowell strike of 1903; it was in 
 1889, when 9000 weavers in thirty-four mills at Fall River 
 struck for a 10 per cent increase in wages. After staying 
 out only seventeen days they returned to work on the old 
 terms. x 
 
 Thus when the Greek, Portuguese, and Polish strikers 
 in 1903 surrendered after nine weeks of idleness, during 
 which they received no aid from the unions, they gave 
 an exhibition in endurance and adherence to a common 
 purpose, that was far above the average for any race of 
 cotton-mill operatives. Moreover, since the proportion of 
 the strikers who returned to the mills on the first day varied 
 from one third to two thirds, whereas the proportion of 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans among the operatives 
 was less than one third, 2 it is evident that a good many of 
 the English-speaking operatives must have surrendered 
 simultaneously with the Southern and Eastern Europeans. 
 
 The history of this strike is prefaced by the Commission 
 with the following remark: 
 
 // is not thought that the presence of immigrants in such large numbers 
 in Community A has exerted a decisive influence upon the success of trade- 
 unionism in the community. The weakness of the unions in Community 
 A is to be traced to less general causes of a local character. 
 
 The reader is at a loss to reconcile this conclusion, and 
 the facts leading up to it, with the general statement, 
 
 1 Tenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, vol. I, Table I, 
 pp. 364-414- 
 
 a In 1909 the proportion was 34 per cent, but in 1900 only 13.2 per cent; 
 the proportion in 1903 must have been somewhere between these two 
 figures. 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, p. 291. 
 
The Cotton Mills 381 
 
 quoted above from the abstract of the reports on immigrants 
 in manufacturing and mining, to the effect that "the more 
 recent immigrant employees from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe and Asia . . . have been a constant menace to the 
 labor organizations, and have been directly and indirectly 
 instrumental in weakening the unions and threatening 
 their disruption." 1 
 Considering : 
 
 (1) That the unskilled operatives have at no time been 
 organized ; 
 
 (2) That the recent immigrants seldom advance to the 
 skilled crafts ; 
 
 (3) That when they do advance to skilled occupations 
 they either join the unions of their crafts or stand by the 
 unions though not affiliated with them; 
 
 (4) That with the machinery heretofore in use there 
 has been no room for competition between organized 
 skilled operatives and unorganized immigrant unskilled 
 la borers ; 
 
 (5) That in past strikes the recent immigrants have stood 
 by the strikers and have never acted as strike-breakers: 
 
 It is evident that the presence of recent immigrants has 
 been no hindrance to union activity. The failure of the 
 unions to secure better terms from the mill corporations 
 than they did must therefore be due to other causes than 
 immigration. 
 
 The real cause of low wages in the cotton mills of New 
 England is the competition of the Southern cotton mills. 
 The subject is only hinted at in the report of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission. No immigrants being employed in the 
 Southern mills, the latter were apparently considered 
 beyond the scope of the Commission's investigation. A 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i., p. 537. Unfortu- 
 nately, the full report on cotton manufacturing has been printed only 
 as a Senate document and is accessible to a very limited number of 
 readers, whereas the misleading conclusions of the abstract on immi- 
 gration in manufacturing and mining have received wide circulation 
 through the free mailing list of the Commission. 
 
382 Immigration and Labor 
 
 thorough discussion of the subject is found in the report of 
 the Massachusetts Bureau of Labor Statistics for 1906. 
 
 Comparing labor conditions in New England and South- 
 ern mills, the Massachusetts report says, by inference, 
 that when the sons and daughters of the farmers of the 
 surrounding country were replaced in the Northern mills 
 by foreigners, strikes and lockouts followed, and the doors 
 were opened to the trade unions, with the result that hours 
 of labor were reduced, wages were increased, and child 
 labor was restricted. 1 The development of the cotton 
 manufacturing industry in the South, with its natural 
 advantages and "cheap labor," has made successful 
 competition impossible for Massachusetts mills, unless 
 Massachusetts will "retrograde and increase its hours of 
 labor, reduce its wages, and employ its children to meet the 
 South in a battle on its own ground. " a 
 
 The ' 'cheap labor" of the Southern cotton mills is the labor 
 of the native white of native stock, who constitute 99 per 
 cent of all cotton-mill operatives in North Carolina, 97 per 
 cent in Georgia and Alabama. 3 The average yearly earnings 
 of the Southern operatives compared as follows with those of 
 the New England operatives, many of whom were Southern 
 and Eastern European, Armenian, and Syrian immigrants : 
 
 1 "When the native stock is all employed, the South must look to the 
 immigrant, and then will come the test of her ability to withstand the 
 enactment of just labor laws. She will be compelled to readjust her 
 hours of labor, increase her wages, discharge her child labor, and open 
 her doors to the trade union. She will go through the same experience 
 as the North. The North's first operatives were the sons and daughters 
 of the native farmers round about, but the grandchildren would not 
 follow in their parents' footsteps, preferring to go into other business. 
 This the South is finding to be the case with the children they are 
 attempting to educate, and foreigners must soon be taken to replace 
 them. Then will come a repetition of the experience of the Northern 
 mills. Strikes and lockouts will follow." Thirty- Sixth Annual Report 
 Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor (1906), Part II: Cotton 
 Manufactures in Massachusetts and the Southern States, p. 102. 
 
 Ibid., p. 1 06. 
 
 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 41 (computed). 
 
The Cotton Mills 
 
 383 
 
 TABLE 114. 
 
 AVERAGE YEARLY EARNINGS OF COTTON-MILL OPERATIVES, BY SEX AND 
 AGE IN THE PRINCIPAL STATES, 1904. x 
 
 State 
 
 Men 
 
 Women 
 
 Children under 
 I 6 years 
 
 New Hampshire 
 
 $4.18 
 
 $7-17 
 
 $188 
 
 Massachusetts . . ... 
 
 4.IO 
 
 74.0 
 
 27-1 
 
 Rhode Island 
 
 4.00 
 
 2-14. 
 
 222 
 
 Connecticut 
 
 5Q2 
 
 7.2 c 
 
 2IO 
 
 New York 
 
 JQ4. 
 
 'MO 
 
 1 88 
 
 
 524. 
 
 714. 
 
 IQ-l 
 
 Norfh Carolina 
 
 2^6 
 
 IQ4, 
 
 T 7.0 
 
 South Carolina ... . 
 
 24.4, 
 
 IQO 
 
 *o" 
 1 18 
 
 Georgia . . 
 
 28l 
 
 TOO 
 
 126 
 
 Alabama . . 
 
 272 
 
 2OS 
 
 T7O 
 
 
 
 
 
 As can be seen from the preceding table the average 
 earnings of adult men in South Carolina are only slightly 
 above the average earnings of children in Massachusetts; 
 the highest average earnings of adult men in the Southern 
 mills are much below the average earnings of women 
 employed in the Northern mills. This is a reversal of the 
 usual relation between men's and women's wages. It is this 
 competition of the cheap American labor of the Southern 
 mills that keeps down the wages of the Southern and East- 
 ern European, Armenian, and Syrian immigrants employed 
 in the cotton mills of the North. 
 
 1 Census of Manufactures, 1905, vol. i., Table 5, p. 188. 
 
CHAPTER XIX 
 
 THE WOOLEN MILLS 
 
 THE recent strike in the woolen mills of Lawrence has 
 forcibly drawn public attention to the condition of 
 labor in the woolen industry. It developed in the hearings 
 held before the Committee of the House of Representatives, 
 and through investigations made by leading magazine 
 writers and social workers, that m this Industry^ protected 
 from foreign competition by the tariff and from domestic 
 competition by a high degree of centralization, the wages of 
 married men were insufficient for the support of their 
 families. The fact that the strikers were mostly recent 
 immigrants diverted the discussion from the issues of the 
 strike to the subject of immigration. It was readily be- 
 lieved that they had been " imported" because of their 
 low standard of living, for the express purpose of reducing 
 the wages of native American and other English-speaking 
 operatives. Professor Lauck, author of the report of the 
 Immigration Commission on "Immigrants in Industries," 
 writing in the North American Review on the Lawrence 
 strike, claimed that 
 
 the American mill hand . . . because of his inability to work under 
 the same conditions and at the same wages as the recent immigrant, has 
 been forced to leave the woolen-goods manufacturing industry. 1 
 
 It has been taken as a self-evident truth that the wages of 
 the recent immigrants were low because they lived in con- 
 
 'W. Jett Lauck: "The Lesson from Lawrence," North American 
 Review, May, 1912, p. 664. 
 
 384 
 
The Woolen Mills 385 
 
 gested quarters, and because they were underfed and poorly 
 clad. There has accordingly been little disposition among 
 people usually friendly to labor to waste sympathy upon 
 men and women who were "willing" to deny themselves 
 the barest necessities of life for the mere privilege of work- 
 ing in the mills. "The lesson from Lawrence" is to these 
 good people that the solution of the labor problem is in 
 keeping out the foreign laborer. As usual in all arguments 
 inspired by this theory, no regard is paid to historical 
 perspective. 
 
 The American operative was not "forced to leave the 
 woolen-goods manufacturing industry" by the coming of 
 the recent immigrants, because he had left it long before. 
 According to the census of 1880, there were among the 
 10,395 operatives of the cotton and woolen mills of Law- 
 rence only 41 1 1 native Americans, i. e., only 40 per cent, in- 
 cluding persons of native and of foreign parentage. The 
 majority were immigrants from Ireland, Great Britain, and 
 Canada, with a sprinkling of Germans (4 per cent). 1 The 
 immigrants from all other countries numbered I per cent 
 of all operatives. Thus, if the prevalence of immigrants 
 among the operatives be the result of the "forcing out" 
 of native Americans, it is clear that they were forced out by 
 English-speaking immigrants. 
 
 Even as recently as 1900 the immigrants from Italy, 
 Russia, Poland, and Austria-Hungary and their American- 
 born children, employed in the woolen and worsted mills of 
 Lawrence, numbered only 721 persons of both sexes, i. e., 
 10 per cent of all operatives, whereas the total number of 
 native Americans of native parentage did not exceed 
 374, i. e., 5.2 per cent of the total force. 2 If it be true that 
 all but this little remnant of American operatives had been 
 "forced out" of the mills, is there any reason to attribute 
 their ousting to the pressure of the 10 per cent made up of 
 "recent immigrants" rather than to that of the 85 per cent 
 
 * Population, X. Census, Table XXXVI., p. 882. 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census Table 43. 
 
386 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 representing the English-speaking immigrants and their 
 native-born children? Suppose the 10 per cent contingent 
 of recent immigrants forced out as many Americans, there 
 were still 90 per cent of the places in the mills to be filled, 
 and the contest for these places was between native Ameri- 
 cans of native parentage and English-speaking immigrants 
 and their children. Detailed figures are given in Table 1 15. 
 
 TABLE 115. 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF THE OPERATIVES OF BOTH SEXES IN THE WOOLEN AND 
 
 WORSTED MILLS OF LAWRENCE, MASSACHUSETTS, BY PARENT 
 
 NATIVITY, 1900.* 
 
 Nativity 
 
 Number 
 
 Percent 
 
 Total 
 
 7I8O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 
 
 
 Native parentage 
 
 374 
 
 5.2 
 
 
 6806 
 
 Q4.8 
 
 
 
 
 Native born 
 
 2005 
 
 27.O 
 
 
 4801 
 
 66. Q 
 
 Country of birth of parents: 
 Canada (English) 
 
 182 
 
 2.6 
 
 Canada (French) 
 
 673 
 
 0.4 
 
 Great Britain 
 
 1^61 
 
 18.9 
 
 Ireland 
 
 2078 
 
 28.9 
 
 Germany 
 
 872 
 
 12.2 
 
 
 7 
 
 .O 
 
 Austria-Hungary 
 
 45 
 
 .6 
 
 Italy 
 
 402 
 
 5.6 
 
 Poland 
 
 no 
 
 1.0 
 
 Russia 
 
 144 
 
 2.O 
 
 Other countries and mixed parentage. . 
 
 911 
 
 12.7 
 
 It is only since the federal census of 1900 that the immi- 
 grants from Southern and Eastern Europe and Syria have 
 become a conspicuous element among the woolen-mill 
 operatives of Lawrence. The report of the Immigration 
 Commission contains figures which "are practically a 
 census of the local establishments " for 1909. According to 
 those figures, 35.5 per cent of the operatives were immigrants 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 43. 
 
The Woolen Mills 
 
 387 
 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe and Turkey. But the 
 proportion of native Americans of native parentage was 
 6.9 per cent, as against 5.2 per cent in 1900. Since the 
 advent of the "new immigrants" the number of native Ameri- 
 cans of native parentage employed in the woolen and worsted 
 mills of Lawrence has more than doubled. The proof of this 
 fact is given in Table 116 next following: 
 
 TABLE 116. 
 
 NUMBER OF NATIVE AMERICANS OF NATIVE PARENTAGE EMPLOYED IN 
 THE WOOLEN AND WORSTED MILLS OF LAWRENCE, IQOO AND 1909. x 
 
 
 1900 
 
 1909 
 
 Per cent 
 increase 
 1900-1909 
 
 Sex 
 
 Woolen 
 mill 
 operatives 
 
 Worsted mill 
 operatives 
 
 Textile mill 
 operatives 
 not otherwise 
 specified. 3 
 
 Total 
 
 Male 
 Female.. . 
 
 Total. 
 
 142 
 147 
 
 33 
 
 52 
 
 45 
 63 
 
 22O 
 262 
 
 690 
 
 545 
 
 213 
 
 108 
 
 289 
 
 85 
 
 108 
 
 482 
 
 1235 
 
 156 
 
 The only inference justified by the figures of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission is that the same economic conditions 
 which have brought the recent immigrants to the Lawrence 
 woolen mills have also induced increasing numbers of native 
 Americans of native stock to accept employment in the 
 same mills. In 1909, the average number of wage-earners 
 in the woolen mills was 20,203, as against an average 
 number of 12,216 employed in igo4. 3 These figures are 
 
 1 Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 43. Report of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission, vol. 10, Table 81, p. 742. The same figures are dupli- 
 cated in Table 85, p. 752. 
 
 2 As some of these operatives may have been employed in woolen 
 and worsted mills, their total number is included in this comparative 
 table. The percentage of increase is thereby reduced below the actual 
 figure. 
 
 * XIIL Census, vol. ix: Manufacturers, p. 527. 
 
388 Immigration and Labor 
 
 indicative of a great expansion of the industry in recent 
 years, which has created new places both for native Ameri- 
 cans and for new immigrants. 
 
 What has been the effect of this expansion upon the 
 rates of wages? Professor Lauck, speaking for the Immi- 
 gration Commission, holds that "the rate of wages in the 
 presence of a large supply of immigrant laborers tends to 
 decline." 1 This obiter dictum, however, is unsupported by 
 figures. The statistics of wages quoted further in the report 
 decidedly contradict the opinion of their compiler. In the 
 thirteen occupations selected by him for comparison, " these 
 figures indicate an apparent increase of 19.65 per cent in the 
 rate of weekly wages . . . during the past twenty years." 
 In another mill the average earnings of weavers show "an 
 increase of 75 per cent." 3 If there be such a tendency as 
 that enunciated by Professor Lauck, its operation has 
 apparently been suspended at Lawrence during the past 
 twenty years. 
 
 The statistics of the Immigration Commission furnish 
 material for a comparison of the variation in the rates of 
 wages in the presence and in the absence of the recent 
 immigrant labor supply, viz., from 1889 to 1899 and from 
 1899 to 1909. In 1890 the population of Lawrence num- 
 bered in all 159 immigrants fr^m Austria, Portugal, Italy, 
 Russia, and Turkey. 3 By 1900, as stated, their number 
 in the woolen mills reached only 8.6 per cent of all opera- 
 tives. Their presence in the mills was certainly a negligible 
 factor in determining the rates of wages. In the ten years 
 following, however, their numbers increased to 35.5 per 
 cent of the total force. As elsewhere, they have taken over 
 "the simpler, cruder processes, " while the English-speaking 
 operatives have been assigned to the higher grades of work. 4 
 It is therefore, possible to observe the effect of recent immi- 
 gration upon the rates of wages for unskilled labor, as well 
 as the effect of the absence of ther competition of recent 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, p. 773. 
 
 Ibid., pp. 773, 774. i Ibid., p. 750. 4 ibid., p. 772, 
 
The Woolen Mills 
 
 389 
 
 immigrants upon the rates of wages in those occupations 
 to which they are not admitted. The comparative rates 
 of increase in the wage scales are presented in Table 117. 
 
 TABLE 117. 
 
 PER CENT INCREASE IN THE RATES OF WAGES PAID BY ONE OF THE 
 
 TWO LARGEST WORSTED MILLS IN LAWRENCE TO SKILLED AND 
 
 UNSKILLED OPERATIVES, IN 1889-1899, AND 1899-1909.* 
 
 Occupation 
 
 Per week 
 
 Per hour 
 
 1889-1899 
 
 1899-1909 
 
 1889-1899 
 
 1899-1909 
 
 Skilled: 
 Loom fixers . . . . 
 
 0.0 
 
 4.7 
 
 0.0 
 
 16.7 
 
 5-3 
 
 0.0 
 
 o.o 
 o.o 
 
 0.0 
 
 16.4 
 23.3 
 5.9 
 
 31.2 
 
 j 8.3) 
 ji8.o[ 
 
 134-3) 
 
 12. 1 
 
 5-5 
 28.9 
 
 16.8 
 
 0.0 
 0.0 
 0.0 
 
 16.7 
 5.3 
 
 0.0 
 
 o.o 
 o.o 
 o.o 
 
 20.5 
 
 0.0 
 
 9.5 
 
 35- 7 x 
 25.0 
 
 I 35 ' ? 
 (40.0) 
 
 16.0 
 
 10. 
 
 33-4 
 
 20.8 
 
 Wool sorters 
 
 Warp dressers 
 
 Unskilled: 
 Doffers 
 
 Spinners . . 
 
 Comb minders 
 
 Drawing girls: 
 Highest grade 
 Lowest grade 
 
 Dyehouse hands 
 
 The preceding table demonstrates : 
 
 (1) That from 1889 to 1899, the rates of wages of the 
 skilled operatives remained stationary, and that they 
 increased from 1899 to 1909, i. e., during the period of the 
 great influx of immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe and Turkey; 
 
 (2) That in three of the unskilled occupations the rates 
 of wages remained stationary in 1889-1899, in the absence 
 of "the new immigration,'* and increased in 1899-1909, in 
 the presence of that immigration ; that the wages of spinners 
 were raised during the earlier period 5.3 per cent and during 
 
 1 The percentages have been computed from the rates per week and 
 per hour quoted in the Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 10, 
 p. 774. Occupations for which two or more rates were given in 1899 
 and only one in 1889 and 1909 have been omitted. 
 
390 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the recent period from 8.3 to 34.3 per cent; that the 
 wages of doffers increased during the first period 16.7 per 
 cent and during the second, 3 1.2 per cent; 
 
 (3) That since the immigrants from Southern and East- 
 ern Europe and Asiatic Turkey have begun to enter the 
 unskilled occupations in large numbers, the percentage of 
 increase in the wages of unskilled operatives has been greater 
 than the percentage of increase in the rates of skilled workers, 
 who are practically all of the English-speaking races. 
 
 If the rates of wages are affected by the racial charac- 
 teristics of the immigrants, then the preceding figures 
 admit of no other conclusion than that the immigrants 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe and Asiatic Turkey 
 have a racial "tendency" to push the wages upward, 
 whereas the English-speaking workmen are willing to 
 acquiesce for a long time (10 years) in such wages as the 
 recent immigrants would consider unsatisfactory. This 
 palpably unsound conclusion is the logical consequence of 
 the false assumption underlying the report of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission on immigrants in manufacturing. The 
 only other possible interpretation of the preceding table of 
 variations in the rates of wages is that the wages remained 
 stationary in 1889-1899 because the growth of the woolen 
 industry was slow during those years and that the wages 
 increased in 1899-1909 owing to the rapid expansion of the 
 woolen industry, which created an active demand for labor. 
 The rapid increase of the number of recent immigrant em- 
 ployees was the effect of the increased demand for labor at 
 higher wages. 
 
 The growth of a Western city, like Los Angeles, from a 
 city of 102,000 inhabitants in 1900 to one of 319,000 in 1910 
 through migration of native citizens, is accepted by the 
 American public as a matter of course. But the average 
 American, being out of touch with the strange peoples 
 whom he sees filling the mills of feis growing city, does not 
 realize the simple fact that "the channel of communication 
 between the economic opportunity or labor demand in the 
 
The Woolen Mills 391 
 
 United States and the labor supply abroad is ordinarily 
 the oral or written accounts of immigrants who have worked 
 in the worsted and cotton mills." The native resident of 
 Lawrence, who may never have been as far away from home 
 as New York, cannot imagine how these thousands of 
 strangers could have found their way to his town without 
 "some organized effort." "Everywhere one goes in the 
 city tales are told of the efforts made by one woolen com- 
 pany to procure laborers in Europe." 1 The Commission 
 has made an effort to investigate these tales with the 
 following results: 
 
 One informant had a cousin in Glasgow who had written concerning 
 pictures of the new mill which he had seen, and concerning an agent of 
 the woolen company. Nothing more definite could be learned. Another 
 informant who was much exercised over reports of this sort had written 
 to the Secretary of the Wool Sorters' Union of Bradford, England, a 
 district said to have been well covered with advertising matter, asking 
 for information. The English trade-union official had, however, seen 
 no advertisements of this sort. A clergyman in close touch with the 
 industrial situation expressed himself as " convinced that agents are sent 
 to Europe to get labor." The priest of the Italian congregation, one of 
 the largest of the foreign churches the greater part of whose member- 
 ship has come from abroad within the past few years states that 
 accounts of the mills and assertions that "wages of $10 a week" are paid 
 have appeared in Italian and other European newspapers.* 
 
 It is evident that in this age of the daily press news of 
 the American labor market travels fast all over the globe. 
 It is not at all impossible that the Table on page 774 of 
 the Report of the Immigration Commission on Cotton Goods 
 Manufacturing, showing that some classes of the operatives 
 in the Lawrence mills earned as much as $14, $15, and even 
 $16 a week, may yet be republished in some Old World 
 newspaper and have the effect of stimulating the immigra- 
 tion of a fresh supply of Italian or Syrian laborers for the 
 Lawrence woolen mills. 
 
 In view of the general conclusion of the Immigration 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. IO., p. 770. 
 'Ibid. 
 
392 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Commission that the recent immigrants are willing to work 
 "indefinitely without protest" for low wages, 1 it is interest- 
 ing to note the characterization of the recent immigrants 
 by a number of superintendents and foremen of the two 
 largest Lawrence mills. "While opinions differ somewhat, 
 there appears to be a considerable uniformity of judgment 
 as to their characteristics." The Italians are quick to 
 leave their positions if they see any apparent advantage 
 elsewhere. One mill superintendent stated that "they no 
 sooner get a job than they want something better; they 
 work in droves; discharge one and they all go." a 
 
 That such characteristics are favorable to concerted 
 action for economic improvement, has been demonstrated 
 by the recent strike of the polyglot working force at the 
 Lawrence mills. An observer whose sympathies were with 
 old-line trade-unionism, noted with surprise that "the 
 capacity of this great host of recent immigrants, represent- 
 ing a number of supposedly alienated nationalities, for 
 continuous, effective solidarity is one of the revelations of 
 the present strike." 3 
 
 The measure of success achieved by these alien strikers 
 can be realized by comparison with the statistics of strikes 
 for the twenty-year period 1881-1900, when the operatives 
 in the woolen and worsted mills of Massachusetts were 
 practically all of the English-speaking races. During that 
 period there were in all 81 strikes, of which only 9 were 
 declared by labor organizations, while 72 were unorganized 
 movements, like the recent strike at Lawrence. The 
 aggregate number of strikers in the State of Massachusetts 
 for the twenty years was only 5618, i. e., about one third of 
 the number engaged in the one recent strike at Lawrence. 
 The aggregate number thrown out of employment by the 
 strikes was 10,144 for the whole period, but 16,117 opera- 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 541. 
 1 Ibid., vol. 10, p. 771. 
 
 T\it, Survey, March 16, 1912, p. 1930: "The Clod Stirs. " By Robert 
 A. Woods, head worker of South End House of Boston. 
 
The Woolen Mills 393 
 
 tives remained at work while the strikes were on. Of the 
 83 mills involved only 31 were forced to close while 52 were 
 able to run with the majority that remained at work. * 
 
 Thus with all odds against them, the recent immigrants 
 speaking in sixteen different languages, have given proof 
 of far greater cohesion than the English-speaking operatives 
 of former years. 
 
 x Sixteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table iv. t 
 pp. 332-355- 
 
CHAPTER XX 
 
 THE IRON AND STEEL WORKERS 
 
 THE twelve-hour day, the twenty-four-hour shift, and 
 Sunday labor, not as an emergency, but as an integral 
 part of the system, have of late caused wide discussion 
 of the iron and steel industry. The public conscience 
 demanded to know who was responsible for those labor 
 conditions. The offenders were easily discovered. Inas- 
 much as three fourths of the unskilled men working those 
 long hours were found to be Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans, it became evident that it was they who were to 
 blame for accepting such intolerable working conditions. 
 A representative of a labor constituency, speaking on the 
 floor of Congress, declared that "in the steel mills of 
 Pittsburgh, Chicago, and Milwaukee, where thirty years 
 ago the so-called princes of labor used to get from $10 to 
 $15 a day, the modern white coolies get $1.75 for twelve 
 hours a day, seven days in the week," the change being 
 due to the "Slavonians, Italians, Greeks, Russians, and 
 Armenians," who "have been brought into this country by 
 the million 1 ' and "simply because they have a lower stand- 
 ard of living . . . have crowded out the Americans, Germans, 
 Englishmen, and Irishmen, " from the mills. x 
 
 Such generalizations as these represent the popular con- 
 ception of the causes of long hours and low wages in the 
 iron and steel industry. The principal fallacy underlying 
 
 'Speech of Hon. Victor L. Berger,-of Wisconsin, in the House of 
 Representatives, Wednesday, June 14, 1911. Congressional Record, pp. 
 2026-2030. 
 
 394 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 395 
 
 this interpretation has been shown in Chapter VII.: there 
 has been no "crowding out" of American, English, Irish, 
 or German steel workers by immigrants "brought" from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. The development of the 
 iron and steel industry has been so rapid that all but a 
 small percentage of the English-speaking workmen have 
 been advanced to higher positions and their places have 
 been filled with Southern and Eastern Europeans. The 
 new immigrants do not compete with the native and older 
 immigrant workmen, and can therefore not affect their 
 wages. 4fc 
 
 The parallel between the "princes of labor" and the 
 "white coolies" is equaljpr without an historical foundation. 
 Princes have at all times been few. "The old reputation 
 of the steel industry as one of exceptionally high wages is 
 false so far as the rank and file are concerned," says Mr. 
 Fitch of the Pittsburgh Survey staff, who has made a study 
 of the steel workers, "neither, on the other hand, should it 
 be singled out as an unusual type, as an industry in which 
 the majority of the men are paid at the lowest rates." 1 
 The rollers, heaters, and other skilled men, whose earnings 
 in the early days often exceeded the salary of the superin- 
 tendent, were only a small fraction of the total force. 
 
 The high earnings of the few skilled men often repre- 
 sented profit rather than wages. In the early '80 's the 
 contract system was the prevailing method of hiring labor 
 in the mills: 
 
 A man would contract with the company to run a single mill, from the 
 furnaces to the piling beds of the shears, and like any other contractor 
 he derived his profit from the margin between what the company paid 
 him for the tonnage turned out and what he paid the men for it. The 
 contractor, while usually known as the roller, frequently did no work 
 at all, having two practical rollers employed on the mill. At the same 
 time he secured a considerable income for himself by paying the men as 
 low wages as possible, and steel workers got a reputation for being very 
 highly paid workmen on account, of the large earnings of these contractors. 
 A statement from the proprietor of one of the "largest rolling mills in 
 
 1 John A. Fitch, " The Steel Workers." The Pittsburgh Survey, p. 150. 
 
396 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the District," regarding wages paid in his mill in 1881-1882, was to the 
 effect that under the contract system one steel worker had made $25,000 
 in a year. A sheet shearer made $12.00 per day and paid his helper 
 $2.00. A hammerman in charge of both turns made $i 7.00 per day and 
 paid his helper $2.50.' 
 
 The proportion of employees who were paid each rate 
 of wages in the rolling mills of Ohio in 1884, when the 
 number of Southern and Eastern Europeans among them 
 was negligible, appears from Table 118. The number of 
 
 TABLE 
 
 -C/ llO^k 
 
 SELECTS? ROLLING 
 
 f 
 
 CLASSIFICATION OF EMPLOYEES IN SELECTEU ROLLING MILLS OF OHIO 
 BY RATES OF WEEKLY WAGES, 1884.' 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 Rates of weekly 
 wages 
 
 Skilled* 
 
 Semi- 
 
 skilled 
 
 Laborers 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Under j 
 
 $IOtOj 
 
 10 
 \12 
 
 
 
 
 
 699 
 360 
 
 699 
 360 
 
 32-3 
 16.9 
 
 $12 to* 
 
 5l5 
 
 
 
 199 
 
 
 199 
 
 9 .6 
 
 $15 to 1 
 
 >i8 
 
 
 
 95 
 
 
 
 95 
 
 4-5 
 
 $18 to \ 
 $25 to J 
 
 ^25 
 flO 
 
 415 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 419 
 H7 
 
 19.6 
 6.9 
 
 $30 to $60 
 
 158 
 
 
 
 
 
 158 
 
 7-5 
 
 $60 and over 
 
 57 
 
 
 
 
 
 57 
 
 2.7 
 
 Total 
 
 777 
 
 298 
 
 1059 
 
 2134 
 
 100.0 
 
 "princes of labor" did not exceed 57 in a total force of 
 2134, i. e., 2.7 per cent. On the other hand, the number of 
 "white coolies" who were paid less than $10 a week, i. e., 
 less than $1.75 per day, was then as high as one third of the 
 total force, and those who were paid less than $12 a 
 week numbered nearly one half of all employees. There is 
 no reason to assume that the wages in Ohio materially 
 
 1 Fitch, loc. /., p. 99. 
 
 'Report of the Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1885, Table 51, pp. 
 185-186. The statistics comprise only those mills for which complete 
 data were available. 
 
 Includes: Rollers, nailers, heaters, and puddlers. 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 397 
 
 differed from those paid at the time in other centers of the 
 iron and steel industry. 
 
 The Immigration Commission made a comparative 
 statistical study of the rates of wages paid by one steel 
 company at different periods, going as far back as 1880, 
 and reached the following conclusion: 
 
 An inspection of the wage scale paid by the steel company during the 
 past eighteen years the period marked by the coming of the immigrants 
 in greatest numbers reveals the fact that wages have risen and fallen 
 in good and bad times equally for skilled labor, largely free from direct 
 immigration competition, and for unskilled labor, now largely per- 
 formed by immigrants. 1 
 
 The wage scale appearing in the report includes no rolling 
 mills where exceptionally high rates were earned by a few 
 men of special skill. The highest rate appearing in the 
 scale for 1 880 is $3 per day paid to engineers ; the highest 
 in 1885 is $3.42 for brick masons. Neither of these two 
 classes were iron and steel workers in a proper sense. The 
 highest paid among iron and steel workers proper in 1880 
 were boiler-makers, whose maximum rate was $2.75. But 
 the wages of laborers in 1880 were as low as $1.10, and in 
 1885 as low as $i. There was a general drop in the 
 rates of wages at the blast furnaces and in the Bessemer 
 department between 1880 and 1885, when immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern Europe was insignificant. 
 There was also a drop in the rates for several occupations 
 from 1890 to 1895, which was obviously due to the effects 
 of the crisis of 1893. Since 1895 wages at the blast furnaces 
 and in the Bessemer department have been on the increase, 
 while in the mechanical department, the wages of skilled 
 mechanics have been subject to sharp fluctuations. On the 
 other hand, the wages of unskilled laborers, most of whom 
 are from Southern and Eastern Europe, have steadily 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, p. 601. 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 risen, while the pay of the engineers, who are mostly "Eng- 
 lish-speaking, " has not come up to the 1880 level. A 
 summary of the figures is given in Table 119 next below. 1 
 
 TABLE 119. 
 
 DAILY WAGES OF EMPLOYEES IN STEEL COMPANY NO. I, l88o-I9O8. 
 
 
 Laborers 
 
 Other unskilled or 
 semi-skilled 
 
 All others 
 
 Year 
 
 Lowest 
 
 Highest 
 
 Lowest 
 
 Highest 
 
 Lowest 
 
 Highest 
 
 1880 
 
 $I.IO 
 
 $1.23 
 
 $1.05 
 
 $1-55 
 
 $1.60 
 
 $3.00 
 
 1885 
 
 I.OO 
 
 1.04 
 
 .68 
 
 1.48 
 
 1-54 
 
 342 
 
 1890 
 
 I.OO 
 
 I.IO 
 
 75 
 
 1.25 
 
 1.26 
 
 2.70 
 
 1895 
 
 I.OO 
 
 I.IO 
 
 I.OO 
 
 1-35 
 
 145 
 
 3.00 
 
 I90O 
 
 I.OO 
 
 1.20 
 
 1.15 
 
 1.50 
 
 1-55 
 
 3-65 
 
 1903 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.30 
 
 I.IO 
 
 2.IO 
 
 2.25 
 
 3-24 
 
 1908 
 
 1.38 
 
 145 
 
 1. 20 
 
 2.2O 
 
 2.25 
 
 3-60 
 
 As stated, the wage statistics of the Immigration Com- 
 mission do not include rolling mills. From data published 
 by the Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics it appears that the 
 average wages of laborers in rolling mills increased, from 
 1884 to 1902, 50 per cent, as shown in Table 120: 
 
 TABLE 120. 
 
 COMPARATIVE WAGES OF LABORERS IN ROLLING MILLS, OHIO, 1884-1902.' 
 
 Year 
 
 Number reported 
 
 Average daily wages 
 
 1884 
 1902 
 
 4,134 
 11,560 
 
 $1.05 
 1-58 
 
 An intelligent comparison of the wages of iron and steel 
 workers at present and in the period preceding the immigra- 
 
 1 For details of the scale, see Appendix, Table XXV. 
 Reports of the Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1885, p. 187; 1903, p. 
 429. 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 399 
 
 tion of Southern and Eastern Europeans must take into 
 consideration the revolution in technical methods which has 
 occurred in the iron and steel industry during the interven- 
 ing years. Prior to 1890, less than one half of all pig iron 
 produced was made into steel; in 1909 all but 7 per cent of 
 the pig iron reached the market as steel. Until 1890 the 
 manufacture of iron other than steel exhibited a rapid 
 growth; from 1880 to 1890 its output doubled. Since the 
 latter year, however, it began to decline; from 5,000,000 
 tons in 1890 it dropped to about 1,800,000 tons in 1909. 
 The majority of the men who had acquired skill in the iron 
 mills found their occupations gone. Judged by the ton- 
 nage of pig iron, the change must have affected as many 
 iron workers as there had been employed in all the mills in 
 1887. At the same time the production of steel has in- 
 creased sixfold since 1890.* This marvelous growth was 
 made possible only by the adoption of new methods of 
 steel-making. All these changes necessitated a thorough 
 readjustment of the laboring forces. The transformation 
 is well described in the following excerpts from Mr. Fitch's 
 study of The Steel Workers: 
 
 Through the revolutionary changes in method, machinery has dis- 
 placed men to a remarkable extent. The proportion of skilled steel 
 workers needed for the operation of a plant has decreased. At the 
 same time, the large companies have so increased their capacity that 
 they are employing more men than ever before, until to-day 60 per cent 
 of the men employed in the steel industry are unskilled, and that 60 
 per cent is greater in numbers than the total working force twenty 
 years ago. In no part of the steel manufacture have inventions and 
 improvements had such an effect upon working conditions as in the 
 rolling mills. Twenty years ago these mills were alive with men. To- 
 day you will find large numbers of men in the guide and merchant mills, 
 but at the blooming mills, the plate mills, and the structural and rail 
 mills, you have to look sharply not to miss them entirely. These mills 
 have become largely automatic. The two improvements that have 
 contributed most to the cutting-down of the laboring force are the 
 electric crane and the movable roll tables. . . . The electric crane 
 
 1 Computed from Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1911, p. 710. 
 
400 Immigration and Labor 
 
 operates over the whole length of the mill. Heavy material, that 
 formerly a dozen moved with difficulty, is now picked up and moved 
 easily by two men, working with a crane. Roll changing has become an 
 easier and swifter process through the aid of the crane, and practically 
 all the heavy lifting and carrying within the mill is thus accomplished 
 by electric power. ... As in the case of blast furnace improvements, 
 the effect has been to reduce the number of men employed. . . . 
 
 This tendency to make processes automatic has resulted not only in a 
 lessened cost with an increased tonnage, but it has also reinforced the 
 control of the employers over their men. When the roll tables were 
 introduced, they threw many roughers and catchers out of employment; 
 beyond that, they lessened the importance to the employers of the men 
 remaining. Men can learn to pull levers more easily than they can 
 reach the skilled mastery of a position where the greatest dependence 
 is on the man and the least on the machine. Accordingly this develop- 
 ment has lessened the value to the employer of all the men in a plant, and 
 at the same time has made the job of every man, skilled and unskilled, 
 to a greater or less degree insecure. . . . The aim to-day seems to be 
 to make the whole process as mechanical as possible. Fifteen or twenty 
 years ago a large proportion of the employees in any steel plant were 
 skilled men. The percentage of the highly skilled has steadily grown 
 less, and the percentage of the unskilled has as steadily increased. 
 The plants of the Carnegie Steel Company in Allegheny County employ 
 in seasons of prosperity an aggregate of over 23,000 men. Of these 
 about 17 per cent are skilled, 21 per cent semi-skilled, and 62 per cent 
 unskilled, according to the classification employed by the company. 1 
 
 Taking the classification of Table 118 as a standard of 
 comparison, we find that in 1884 more than one third of 
 all men employed in rolling mills were skilled, whereas by 
 1907 their proportion had shrunk to 17 per cent. Had 
 there been no expansion in the steel industry, more than one 
 half of the skilled men employed in 1884 would have been 
 reduced to the semi-skilled grade. But as the growth of 
 production outran the progress of labor-saving methods 
 and machinery, the skilled and semi-skilled men who were 
 displaced from one department were absorbed in others, 
 and still there were openings in the higher grades which were 
 filled by promotion from the ranks of the older unskilled 
 men. Of course the whole trend of the technical progress 
 
 1 Fitch t loc. tit., pp. 3-4, 55-56, 139-141- 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 401 
 
 in the steel industry being toward elimination of human 
 skill, the advancement of the minority to skilled and semi- 
 skilled positions depended upon the employment of ever- 
 increasing numbers of unskilled laborers. For reasons 
 explained in Chapter VIII., 
 
 English, Irish, and German immigration began to fall off at just about 
 the time that the steel industry began to expand so rapidly and at the 
 same time to introduce the automatic processes. This created a tre- 
 mendous market for unskilled labor just as the field of immigration 
 was shifting from Northwestern to Southeastern Europe. Slavs coming 
 to America to perform the unskilled manual labor, and finding it in the 
 steel industry, sent for their relatives and neighbors. These automatic 
 accretions, through letters and friends returning to the old country and 
 spreading the tidings of where work is to be had, are at once the most 
 natural and most widespread factors in mobilizing an immigrant labor 
 force. 1 
 
 Mr. Fitch is careful to note that "the newer immigrants 
 are not working for less pay for a day's rough work than the 
 races they replaced. The money wages paid for common 
 labor in the Pittsburgh steel mills have been going up during 
 the period referred to. " 2 It is clear that the recent immi- 
 grants were not "brought" to this country to undercut 
 the wages of the older employees. 
 
 The Irish were -not driven out of the blast furnaces by a fresh immi- 
 gration with lower standards of living [says Mr. Fitch further]; rather 
 the conditions in the industry the twelve-hour day, the days and the 
 weeks without a day of rest, the twenty-four-hour shift made the life 
 intolerable. They could make as good a living working fewer hours 
 a day, and only six days in the week, in other positions and in other 
 industries. So the Irish worker went out and the Slav came in. 3 
 
 The effect of these readjustments on the distribution of 
 the working force by race and occupation in the Pittsburgh 
 district can be seen from Table 121. 
 
 The average proportion of Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans among the iron and steel workers, according to the 
 investigations of the Immigration Commission, was 44.5 
 
 1 Fitch, loc. cit. t p. 143. Ibid., pp. 142-143. 
 
 * Ibid., p. 146. 
 
402 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 > 
 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 IO 
 
 VO 
 
 IO M I>.M OJ VO 
 N IO W COOO 00 
 
 vq to 
 
 
 
 
 
 'S 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 Q\ ^ HH M O O 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 
 S 
 
 1 
 
 -juras 
 
 N 
 
 N co CONM " 
 
 CO M 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 M 
 
 vO O N 0000 Tj- 
 
 tt O 
 
 
 1 
 
 i 
 
 1 
 
 WIPE 
 
 ^ 
 
 O O ON cO d IO 
 ^Ci COCO 
 
 ON CO 
 
 
 j> 
 
 1 
 
 t 
 
 HV 
 
 
 
 8 
 
 o o o o o o 
 
 88 8888 
 
 O 
 
 8 8 
 
 
 1 
 
 4* 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 
 >> 
 
 
 
 O'OOI 
 
 to co vqvq vq rt- 
 t* t^ 
 
 i^ q 
 
 M 00 
 
 
 Jj 
 
 
 '> 
 
 
 
 
 t^-tO I>.N ON 
 
 VO ON 
 
 
 80 
 ON 
 M 
 
 ^ - 
 
 
 rt 
 
 a 
 a 
 
 ?tuS 
 
 
 
 t>. M M OO ONM 
 CO M co 
 
 t>- O 
 
 to n- 
 
 Is 
 
 i s 
 
 
 i 
 
 
 
 
 O t*^ ON ON O to 
 
 00 U". 
 
 
 la 
 
 ~- w a 
 
 
 1 
 
 P * nPIS 
 
 8 
 
 OO M l^- M ON M 
 IO MM 
 
 t^. O 
 
 00 M 
 
 H 
 
 j 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 IO * 00 O t>.vO 
 
 CO CO 
 
 CO 
 
 1 S 
 
 
 
 IIV 
 
 8 
 
 M ^^J^^ 
 
 00 O 
 co \O 
 
 ci 
 
 3 II 
 
 
 
 pm^san 
 
 vS 
 CO 
 
 O ON M O oo w 
 M OO CM C< ON N 
 10 M IO10VO ON 
 M" O" 
 
 M 
 
 M O 
 
 to N 
 to vo_ 
 
 H 
 
 fi 
 
 ] 
 
 
 -juia S 
 
 00 
 
 t^ r* OO O *^ ON 
 OO_ IO ^-ON 
 
 M M 
 
 1 
 
 ci cT 
 
 1 
 
 u w 
 
 * 
 
 
 'P'lII^S 
 
 00 
 
 oo 
 CO 
 
 f S5I^ 
 
 to ^* 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 i 
 
 
 
 saptriS 
 
 nv 
 
 CO 
 
 tOM O M CO l>. 
 
 O co c* O Q t> 
 
 t^co oo rt-q o 
 
 IO M" M" COM" 
 
 M 
 
 tQ 
 OO 
 
 00 rf 
 
 
 u 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 K 
 
 h 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 4J 
 
 ro 
 
 
 
 
 Ss 
 
 
 
 
 W rt to 
 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 i 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 i 
 
 
 Race and 
 
 
 i 
 
 a-S c % 
 
 Jllq J ! 
 
 **^ w c is 
 
 *J .,- 'J3 ^3 r> 
 
 W {^ 
 
 ? 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 403 
 
 per cent in the East and 49.4 per cent in the Middle West. * 
 The proportion of Slavs among the employees of the Car- 
 negie Steel Company was accordingly above the average, 
 which ought to emphasize the effects of immigration upon 
 labor conditions in the iron and steel industry. 
 
 The classification of employees by the Carnegie Steel 
 Company is different from that followed in Table 34. a The 
 Immigration Commission draws the dividing line between 
 skilled and unskilled occupations at $1.45 a day, whereas 
 the Carnegie Steel Company includes among the unskilled 
 some occupations with a higher average wage. Moreover, 
 the Immigration Commission has disregarded the semi- 
 skilled class. According to the classification of the company, 
 a little over one sixth of the "unskilled" employees in 1907 
 were English-speaking; of the semi-skilled two fifths were 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe ; among the 
 skilled only one tenth were of the new immigrant races. 
 
 The wages of each of these classes have been variously 
 affected by the changes in machinery and methods. The 
 wages of unskilled laborers, five sixths of whom are immi- 
 grants from Southern and Eastern Europe, "have increased 
 in the last few years. In 1892 they received 14 cents an 
 hour at Homestead. In 1907-08 their pay was i6j^ cents 
 an hour in the mills of the United States Steel Corporation 
 an advance of 18 per cent over the hourly pay of 1892. 
 This increase fell short by 4 per cent in keeping pace with 
 the increased cost of necessities as indicated by the Bureau 
 of Labor Bulletin. ... In May, 1910, announcement 
 was made of a general increase in wages for all employees 
 of the United States Steel Corporation. It was described 
 as approximating 6 per cent over existing rates. Common 
 laborers' pay was increased in the mills of the Corporation 
 in the Pittsburg district from i6j^ cents an hour to 17^2 
 cents. This is an increase of 25 per cent over the 14-cent 
 rate paid in 1892. " 
 
 1 Compiled from the Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, 
 Table 23, pp. 34-35. 3 See Chapter VII. 
 
404 Immigration and Labor 
 
 At the opposite extreme are placed, by Mr. Fitch, "the 
 men of highest skill, headed by the rollers and heaters, who 
 have gangs working under them and are practically fore- 
 men. These men represent not over 5 per cent of all 
 employees." They are only a minority among the men 
 classed by the company as skilled. Of the latter class, as 
 stated, only one tenth are Southern and Eastern Europeans ; 
 it is reasonably certain, however, that none of them are 
 among "the men at the top." 1 These "aristocrats of 
 labor" have had their earnings reduced since 1892. The 
 cuts vary, according to position, from 5.39 per cent to 41.20 
 per cent. 
 
 The intermediate 35 per cent are "the real steel workers. 
 . . . They are men skilled in steel manufacture. . . . 
 These men are individually essential to the industry.''' 
 Their wages have remained in a "stationary condition, 
 and if compared with the increased cost of living," exhibit 
 a "downward tendency. " The proportion of Slavs among 
 them can be estimated at 31 per cent. 2 This class holds in 
 every respect an intermediate place; they have not fared 
 as well relatively as the immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe who form the bulk of the unskilled force ; 
 still with one third among them drawn from the new immi- 
 gration they have done better than the "aristocrats of 
 labor" who do not come in contact with the new immigrants. 
 
 The question arises, has not the competition of the Slav 
 prevented the wages of the skilled men below the grade of 
 foreman from rising apace with the cost of living? An 
 
 1 " I was unable to learn of any Slavs who had worked up to positions 
 as rollers or heaters in the Pittsburgh mills," says Miss Byington in her 
 study of Homestead. "This is due without doubt to the poorer 
 industrial equipment of the immigrants, as well as to the unwillingness 
 of the foremen to give the better positions to them.*' The Pittsburgh 
 Survey, "Homestead," p. 148. 
 
 "This ratio is obtained by computation from Table 121, allowing 
 5 per cent of all employees for the "men at the top" and placing all 
 skilled and semi-skilled Southern and Eastern Europeans in the inter- 
 mediate class. 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 405 
 
 answer to this question may be found if the wages of the 
 Pittsburgh skilled men are compared with those of the skilled 
 men employed in the Southern mills where there is very 
 little competition from new immigration. 
 
 The boundary line drawn by the Immigration Commis- 
 sion between skilled and unskilled workers $1.45 per 
 day obviously does not fit the conditions in the Pitts- 
 burgh district, where common laborers were paid 16.5 cents 
 per hour previous to the recent raise. The recent report of 
 the United States Bureau of Labor on labor conditions in 
 the iron and steel industry divides all employees into three 
 classes: (i) The lowest class, of the same grade as 
 common laborers, whose earnings are less than 18 cents per 
 hour; (2) the highest class, whose earnings are 25 cents and 
 over per hour; and (3) the intermediate class, from 18 to 
 25 cents. The proportions of these classes in the total 
 number of employees are: 49.7 per cent for the unskilled, 
 23.6 per cent for the skilled, and 26.7 per cent for the inter- 
 mediate. 1 The latter class differs too widely from the 
 intermediate class of the Pittsburgh Survey to be comparable 
 with it. A fairly uniform basis, however, can be selected 
 from the three classifications, as follows : 
 
 (1) From the Pittsburgh Survey: all employees earning 
 over $2.50 per day. 8 
 
 (2) From the report of the Bureau of Labor: all 
 employees earning 25 cents and over, per hour. 
 
 (3) From the report of the Immigration Commission: 
 all male employees 18 years of age and over who earn $17.50 
 and over per week. 
 
 The close similarity of the three groups appears from the 
 comparative table on page 406. 
 
 The proportion of Southern and Eastern Europeans in 
 this grade was 16.1 per cent in the East, while in the South 
 the aggregate of Southern and Eastern Europeans and 
 
 1 Summary of Wages and Hours of Labor from the Report on Conditions 
 of Employment in the Iron and Steel Industry in the United States, p. 26. 
 3 Fitch, loc. tit., Table 8, p. 163. 
 
406 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 negroes in the same grade was only 2.2 per cent. Thus in 
 the East there were relatively about twice as many English- 
 speaking employees receiving the highest rates as in the 
 South, notwithstanding the much higher percentage of 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans competing for the same 
 positions in the East. 
 
 TABLE 122. 
 
 PER CENT OF SKILLED IRON AND STEEL WORKERS, BY LOCATION. 
 
 
 
 
 Earnings 
 
 
 Location 
 
 Source 
 
 250. and 
 over per 
 hour 
 
 $2.50 and 
 over per 
 day 
 
 117.50 and 
 over per 
 week 
 
 Allegheny County 
 Pittsburgh District 
 
 Pittsburgh Survey 
 U. S. Bureau of 
 Labor 
 
 2d 06 
 
 28.17 
 
 
 
 East 
 
 Immigration Com- 
 
 
 
 
 
 mission 
 
 
 
 24..O 
 
 South 
 
 i Immigration ) 
 Commission 
 
 T 1 2fi 
 
 
 I* 6 
 
 
 U. S. Bureau of ( 
 Labor 
 
 
 
 A^.U 
 
 In order to assemble into one group all Southern mill- 
 workers who perform the same grade of labor as the men 
 employed in Eastern mills at $17.50 per week and upwards, 
 we must descend one step and admit all Southern iron and 
 steel workers earning $15 per week. 
 
 As can be seen from Table 123 on page 407, two fifths 
 (42 per cent) of the skilled iron and steel workers in the 
 Southern mills earn only from $15 to $17.50 per week, 
 whereas all employees of the same grade in the Eastern 
 mills are paid not less than $17.50 per week. The differ- 
 ence cannot be explained by the competition of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans or negroesfbecause the aggregate 
 of those two racial groups among Southern iron and steel 
 Corkers earning $15 and over does not exceed 1.8 per cent, 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 
 
 407 
 
 whereas in the Eastern mills the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans constitute 16.1 per cent of all mill men earning 
 $17.50 and upwards. 
 
 TABLE 123. 
 
 PER CENT OF SKILLED IRON AND STEEL WORKERS WITH SPECIFIED 
 EARNINGS IN EASTERN AND SOUTHERN MILLS. 1 
 
 District 
 
 Earnings per week 
 
 Per cent of all 
 employees 
 
 Per cent 
 within the grade 
 
 South 
 
 ($15 to $17.50 
 J $17. 50 and over 
 
 9.8 
 13-6 
 
 4 2 
 58 
 
 East 
 
 ( $15 and over 
 $17. 50 and over 
 
 23-4 
 
 24. O 
 
 100 
 IOO 
 
 
 
 
 
 There is considerable variation in the proportion of 
 skilled and unskilled labor employed in various departments 
 of iron and steel mills. This variation may affect geographi- 
 cal comparisons which take no account of industrial speciali- 
 zation. In order to eliminate this source of error the 
 proportions of employees earning 25 cents per hour and 
 over in productive occupations 2 are compared in Table 
 124 by departments. The figures show that, in all de- 
 partments but one, a larger proportion of all ^employees 
 are paid those rates in the Pittsburgh district than in the 
 South. It may be assumed that the substitution of ma- 
 chinery for human skill in the Pittsburgh district is as far 
 advanced as in the Southern mills; the proportion of skilled 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, pp. 134, 355. 
 
 2 The following table is confined to "productive occupations" in 
 order to exclude from the comparison, as far as possible, others than 
 iron and steel workers. "The wages of workmen in mechanical 
 trades are much more nearly standardized in the different districts 
 than of the employees in the productive occupations, who are depend- 
 ent almost entirely on the iron and steel industry for employment. " 
 Summary of Wages and Hours of Labor in the Iron and Steel Industry, 
 P- 33- 
 
408 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 men in each department of the Pittsburgh mills may, there- 
 fore, be accepted as the standard. It follows, accordingly, 
 that in the Southern mills a fraction varying from one sixth 
 to two thirds of all skilled men are paid less than 25 cents 
 per hour, whereas in the Pittsburgh district all men of the 
 same class are paid 25 cents and over. 
 
 TABLE 124. 
 
 PER CENT OF EMPLOYEES IN EACH DEPARTMENT EARNING 25 CENTS AND 
 OVER PER HOUR, IN THE PITTSBURGH AND THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT. 1 
 
 Department 
 
 Pittsburgh 
 
 South 
 
 Difference 
 
 Per cent of 
 all employees 
 
 Per cent of 
 Pittsburgh 
 ratio 
 
 Puddling mills . . . 
 
 70 
 
 47 
 38 
 36 
 
 II 
 6 
 
 58 
 3i 
 
 22 
 2O 
 
 65 
 
 22 
 2 
 
 12 
 
 -16 
 -16 
 -16 
 
 + 4 
 
 -4 
 
 -17 
 
 -34 
 -42 
 
 -44 
 
 22 
 -6 7 
 
 Blooming mills 
 
 Bar mills 
 
 Bessemer converters. . . . 
 Miscellaneous mills 
 
 Open-hearth furnaces . . . 
 Blast furnaces 
 
 
 The exception noted above applies to eleven miscellaneous 
 rod mills in the United States employing a total of 333 men 
 at 25 cents and over per hour, 2 i. e. t about J per cent of 
 the total in productive occupations. The number is too 
 small to affect the labor situation. 3 
 
 The preceding comparisons lead to the conclusion that 
 the rates of wages of iron and steel workers vary inversely as the 
 ratio of recent immigrants: The wages of the unskilled, 
 the bulk of whom are Slavs, have kept pace with the cost 
 of living; the wages of the "aristocrats of labor," none of 
 whom are Slavs, have been reduced; the money wages of 
 
 1 Summary of Wages and Hours of Labor in the Iron and Steel Indus- 
 try, p. 32. Ibid., pp. 16 and 25. 
 
 a At the present writing the full report of the Bureau of Labor is still 
 in press, while the published summary does not go into details of a 
 local character. 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 409 
 
 other skilled men, two thirds of whom are English-speaking, 
 have remained stationary the wages of this class of em- 
 ployees are lower in the South, where they meet no immi- 
 grant competition, than in the Pittsburgh District. 
 
 This correlation between the percentage of recent immi- 
 grants and the variation of the rate of wages is not the 
 manifestation of some innate racial predisposition to higher 
 wages, but the working of the law of supply and demand 
 in the labor market. The employment of a high percentage 
 of immigrants in any section, industry, or occupation is 
 an indication of an active demand for labor in excess of the 
 native supply. Absence of immigrants is a sign of a dull 
 market for labor. The wages of the unskilled Slav laborers 
 have been raised because of the increasing demand for 
 unskilled labor, not in the steel industry alone, but in other 
 industries as well. The unskilled Slavs "can dig ditches 
 or heave coal any day just as well as they can throw chains 
 around piles of steel billets or shovel scrap into furnaces." 
 On the contrary, the skilled English-speaking steel workers, 
 though "individually essential to the industry . . . could 
 not enter any other industry without a reduction in earn- 
 ing power, because they are skilled only as steel work- 
 ers. " Hence their acquiescence in a lowered rate of wages, 
 whereas the unskilled Slav with his supposedly "lower 
 standard of living" has been able to command as high a 
 wage (measured by purchasing power) as his English- 
 speaking predecessor. 
 
 Long hours and Sunday work have not come with the 
 new immigration. "Sunday work has been general in 
 blast furnaces in this country from the beginning." 2 In 
 rolling mills the practice has varied. There were some 
 mills which ran on Sundays, as far back as the 8o's, before 
 "the Slav invasion." The Amalgamated Association of 
 Iron and Steel Workers in the days of its power raised no 
 objection to labor on Sunday. Its main concern was solely 
 with wages, and it is a historical fact, worthy of notice, 
 
 1 Fitch, loc. cit. t p. 154. * Ibid., p. 168. 
 
410 Immigration and Labor 
 
 that the twelve-hour day was staunchly defended by the 
 organized iron and steel workers when the steel manu- 
 facturers, prompted by technical considerations, attempted 
 to reduce the day to eight hours. 
 
 The twelve-hour day was the outgrowth of metallurgical 
 conditions in the old iron mills. In puddling one charge has 
 to be melted, worked, and taken out before the next can 
 go in. From the beginning of the industry in the Pittsburgh 
 District, five charges or "heats" have been a day's work for 
 a puddler. In the mills rolling sheet iron, too, the working 
 day was determined by the number of heats. In the early 
 days of the iron industry five heats took about twelve hours. 
 This was the basis of the twelve-hour day with the two-shift 
 system. With the progress of improvements in furnace 
 construction and methods, it became possible to finish a 
 turn of five heats in a shorter time and the actual working 
 day gradually shrank to one of ten hours and even less. 
 As a result of the shortened time, there came to be periods 
 of idleness between shifts. In a sheet mill this interim 
 between shifts was especially objectionable, for sheet iron 
 is rolled so thin that good results can be obtained only when 
 the rolls are expanded by the heat. The rolls are so shaped 
 that when cold they cannot turn out a sheet of uniform 
 thickness ; consequently after a period of idleness hot scrap 
 is sent through them until they reach the correct expansion. 
 To avoid these periods of idleness, the manufacturers, in 
 the 8o's, sought to introduce an eight-hour day. This was 
 for a long time resisted by the union, which stood firmly for 
 the twelve-hour shift. The reason for this unusual attitude 
 was that the skilled men who belonged to the union were 
 paid at piece rates and apprehended a loss of a part of their 
 earnings in case they might not be able to turn out five 
 heats in eight hours. The question was discussed at several 
 national conventions. Some of the officers took the ground 
 that a reduction of hours was desirable even if it originally 
 involved a loss of earnings to individuals. The introduc- 
 tion of a three-shift system would create a demand for half 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 411 
 
 as many more skilled men as were employed at the time 
 and would eventually enable the members of the union to 
 win an increase in piece rates. But the rank and file of the 
 membership could not see so far ahead and forced the officers 
 to insist upon the twelve-hour day. Some lodges which 
 had accepted the eight-hour shift were suspended. One 
 of the presidents of the union who supported the manu- 
 facturers in their effort to introduce the eight-hour day was 
 denounced by the membership as a traitor to the cause of 
 labor. The controversy lasted several years in the 8o's, 
 when the iron and steel workers were all of the English- 
 speaking races. Later the union relaxed its rule against 
 the eight-hour system, but the manufacturers had mean- 
 while readjusted themselves to the old twelve-hour shift. 1 
 This episode characterizes the spirit of the Amalgamated 
 Association. 
 
 The Association was originally organized as a union of 
 skilled iron workers and was very strong in the iron industry. 
 But with the decline of the latter the power of the organiza- 
 tion began to wane. It never gained strength in the steel 
 mills. Out of 3800 men at Homestead when the strike 
 began in 1892, only 752 were members in good standing of 
 the Amalgamated Association. "The Association has 
 always been an organization of skilled workers and has 
 centered its efforts on securing better conditions for that 
 class of labor alone, " says Mr. Fitch. " It was only in 1889 
 that the constitution permitted the admission of all men, 
 except, however, common laborers." 2 
 
 Nevertheless, when the Amalgamated Association struck 
 in 1892, the common laborers, the despised Hungarians 
 and Slavs, stood by it. 3 The defeat of the Homestead 
 strike broke the organization. It had been rapidly increas- 
 
 1 See Fitch, loc. cit. t pp. 90-97. * Ibid . pp. 97, 98. 
 
 * "A great cause was in the balance, and in their humble way the 
 army of the poor Hungarians and Slavs understood it, " says a trade- 
 union historian of the Homestead strike. Myron R. Stowell: Fort 
 Prick, or the Siege of Homestead, p. 86, 
 
412 Immigration and Labor 
 
 ing its membership since 1885, when it had numbered only 
 5700, to the year preceding the great strike, when it reported 
 to the national convention a membership of 24,000, organized 
 in 290 lodges. During the year following the strike, it 
 lost about one half of that number. There were slight 
 increases at times in later years; since 1903, however, it 
 has been gradually declining, until it had, in 1910, only 103 
 lodges with a little over 8000 members. x This is less than 
 5 per cent of the total number of iron and steel workers in 
 the United States. 2 
 
 The strength of the organization of the iron and steel 
 workers in the 8o's lay in their special skill. Though a 
 minority of the force, they were indispensable to the indus- 
 try, because they could not be replaced. It is for this very 
 reason that they barred common laborers from their organi- 
 zation: they did not want to become involved in con- 
 troversies over the wages of day laborers who could easily 
 be replaced by others. But when improved machinery 
 displaced the skill of the mechanic the organization of the 
 skilled iron and steel workers lost its foothold. To-day, 
 says Mr. Fitch 
 
 every man is in training for the next position above. If all of the 
 rollers in the Homestead plant were to strike to-morrow the work would 
 go on, and only temporary inconvenience, if any, would be suffered. 
 There would simply be a step up along the line: the tableman would 
 take the rolls, the hooker would manipulate the tables, perhaps one 
 of the shearmen's helpers would take the hooker's position, and some- 
 where, away down the line, an unskilled yard laborer would be taken 
 to fill the vacancy in the lowest position involving skill. The course 
 would vary in the different styles of mills, as the positions vary in 
 number and character, but the operating principle is everywhere the 
 same. In the open hearth department the line of promotion runs 
 through common labor, metal wheelers, stock handlers, cinder-pit man, 
 second helper, and first helper to melter foreman. In this way the 
 companies develop and train their own men. . . . Thus the working 
 
 1 Fitch, loc. cit., p. 297. 
 
 3 In May, 1910, there were 172,706 workers employed in the steel 
 mills of the United States. Summary of Wages and Hours of Labor in 
 the Iron and Steel Industry, p. 17. 
 
The Iron and Steel Workers 413 
 
 force is pyramided and is held together by the ambition of the men 
 lower down; even a serious break in the ranks adjusts itself all but 
 automatically. x 
 
 In 1909, an attempt was made by "the men lower down" 
 to unite all mill workers in a common demand for better 
 terms of employment. In the McKees Rocks strike the 
 leaders and the rank and file were mostly recent immigrants. 
 Of this strike Mr. Fitch has the following to say : 
 
 In the summer of 1909 there was a demonstration of the spirit of 
 immigrant workmen that opened the eyes of the public to qualities 
 heretofore unknown. For many weeks at McKees Rocks they persisted 
 in their strike against the Pressed Steel Car Company. It had been 
 thought that the Slavs were too sluggish to resist their employers, and 
 unable to organize along industrial lines. It was proved in this conflict 
 that neither theory was correct. 3 
 
 'Fitch, loc. cit., pp. 141, 142. 
 Ibid., pp. 237, 238. 
 
CHAPTER XXI 
 
 THE COAL MINERS 
 
 THE Immigration Commission considered the coal- 
 mining industry as typical of the conditions created 
 by immigration, and gave it accordingly the most promi- 
 nent place in its report. Two volumes are devoted to 
 bituminous coal, and a portion of a third to anthracite. 
 The findings of the Commission may be briefly summed up 
 as follows : the English-speaking mine workers do not desire V 
 to associate with the immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, consequently those immigrants are undesirable. 
 There are in the reports some valuable data on the economic 
 side of the question, but they have had no part in shaping 
 the conclusions 6f"the Commission. It views the con- 
 ditions in the coal-mining industry with the eyes of the 
 English-speaking trade-union officials, who apprehend in v 
 the multitudes of Slav and Italian mine workers a growing 
 menace to their influence in the organization. 
 
 To follow the Commission's summary historical review 
 of the coal-mining industry, the conflict between the English- 
 speaking and non-English-speaking races began in the &o&' 
 when a series of unsuccessful strikes forced "a greater or 
 less number of natives, English, Irish, Scotch, and Germans," 
 to leave "Pennsylvania in search of better working con- 
 ditions in the Middle West or the localities in the Southwest 
 or West to which the recent immigrants had not penetrated 
 in important numbers. " The same situation was repeated 
 in the ^30*5 in West Virginia. The "constantly growing 
 number of Southern and Eastern Europeans . . . com- 
 pletely inundated the older employees," with the result 
 
 414 
 
The Coal Miners 415 
 
 that many of them "moved westward in search of better 
 working conditions," and "the immigrants from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe were left in undisputed control of the 
 situation." In their new retreat the English-speaking /? Di- 
 mmers remained undisturbed until the first decade of theT 
 present century, when the advancing columns of the South- 
 ern and Eastern Europeans reached them there. "As the 
 pressure, resulting from the increase in numbers of the recent 
 immigrants has become stronger . . . the older immigrants 
 and natives," who were unable to change their occupation, 
 moved " from localities and Amines where the competition of 
 the Southern and Eastern European has been most strongly 
 felt to other localities in the Middle West or Southwest." 
 But soon the first detachments of the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans made their appearance in the Southwestern 
 fields and forced the "Americans and individual members 
 of the English, Irish, Scotch, and Welsh races" to retreat 
 to New Mexico and Colorado. The narrative concludes 
 with the following statement, which sounds the keynote, as 
 it were, of the whole report : 
 
 From the standpoint of the natives and the older immigrant employees, 
 it therefore seems clearly apparent that the competition of recent immi- 
 grants has caused a gradual displacement, commencing in Pennsylvania '^ 
 and extending westward, until at the present time the representatives 
 of the pioneer employees in the bituminous mining industry are making 
 their last stand in the Southwest, and especially in Kansas, where they 
 are gradually being weakened and are withdrawing to the newly opened 
 fields of the West, to which the recent immigrant has not come in jm- 
 portant numbers. Along with this displacement of the older employees 
 in the different coal-producing areas has proceeded the elimination of a 
 correspondingly large proportion from the industry and the development 
 of such working and Hying conditions that the sons of natives and the 
 second generation of immigrant races have only to a very small extent 
 consented to enter the industry. 1 
 
 The story of the pioneers "making their last stand" 
 against the invaders has a pathetic sound uncommon in 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, p. 536. 
 
PRODUCTION OF COAL IN STATES WITH AN ANNUAL 
 1880 
 
 \20ro39 
 (i unit = 1 ,000,000 tons) 
 
 416 
 
OUTPUT OF NOT LESS THAN I.OOO.OOO TONS. 
 
 IQOO 
 
 .^\ 
 
 . 
 
 . J ^ ^K- ; 
 
 / ^'^.^ ^-.yyyo : . :: . : }_ __ ' 
 
 v WIS. 
 
 
 ^<ir/&^n&M&YMB& ) 
 
 H.G. 
 
 vv:-.. ; v rV ^:/ ; . :; v^:: 
 
 s.c. 
 
 w 
 
 1910 
 
 , 
 
 \i ' ^M^TOk^A^i---^^ 
 
 20ro39 
 (i unit = 1 ,000,000 tons) 
 
 417 
 
4i 8 Immigration and Labor 
 
 official statistical publications. It does not belong, how- 
 ever, to the realm of history. A tribe of Indian huntsmen, 
 retreating before the advancing lines of paleface invaders, 
 could find new hunting-grounds in the untrodden wilds of 
 the West and the Southwest. But the coal miners could 
 not have withdrawn to new territory unless capital had 
 gone there before them, and had opened mines, built houses, 
 and established commissary stores. From an impersonal 
 standpoint "it therefore seems clearly apparent" that the 
 
 "* migrations of the English-speaking miners were the effect 
 of the opening of new coal-field_s in the West andTSouthwest 
 whicn offered better opportunities to the mine worker than 
 the older fields of the East. In the sparsely settled West 
 and Southwest, far away from Eastern competition, coal 
 prices were higher, and the mine operators were in a position- 
 
 v to offer inducements to Eastern miners who were willing 
 to go westward. Turning from the summary to the ma- 
 terials of the Immigration Commission we learn that 
 
 both Kansas and Oklahoma were sparsely settled about 1880, when 
 mining on a large scale was begun, and the management of the properties 
 induced Americans, English, Irish, Scotch, and Welsh to come from the 
 coal regions of Pennsylvania to work in the mines. The first employees 
 *were brought by special car or trainload from the mining localities of 
 Pennsylvania and the Middle West. 
 
 Gradually large numbers of the old employees migrated 
 from the Middle West to the West, the South and South- 
 west "where there was an active demand for experienced 
 miners because of the rapid development of the coal 
 industry. f ' a 
 
 The motive forces of the migration of coal miners from 
 the East to the West and Southwest clearly appear from the 
 statistics of the production of coal by States. A glance 
 at the maps on pp. 416 and 4173 shows that between 1880 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 22 ; vol. 7, pp. 9, 
 II. 15- 'Ibid., vol. 6, pp. 666, 667. 
 
 The figures for these maps are taken from the Report of the United 
 States Geological Survey on Coal, 1910, p. 14. States producing less 
 than 1,000,000 tons are not included. 
 
The Coal Miners 
 
 419 
 
 and 1890 coal mining developed in Virginia, Tennessee, 
 and Alabama in the South; in Oklahoma and Indian Terri- 
 tory in the Southwest; and in Colorado, Montana, and 
 Washington in the West; that between 1890 and 1900 new 
 fields were opened in Michigan, Arkansas, Texas, New 
 Mexico, and Utah; and that while this development was 
 going on in the West and Southwest, production in the old V 
 States was also fast increasing. Alt is plain that the men to 
 work in the new mines had to come from somewhere. The 
 increase of the population of the United States, both by 
 births and immigration, did not keep pace with the growth 
 of coal production, as can be seen from Table 125 next 
 below. The progress of machine mining has been slow: in 
 1910 less than one half (41.74 per cent) of the total output 
 of bituminous coal was machine-mined. 1 Certainly the 
 native population alone was insufficient to supply the in- 
 creasing demand for labor. 2 The extent of the demand 
 can be seen from Diagram XXII. 3 
 
 TABLE 125. 
 
 GROWTH OF POPULATION AND OF THE PRODUCTION OF COAL, l88O-I9IO. 
 
 Year 
 
 Per capita 
 production t 
 
 Per cent of increase for decade 
 
 
 tons. 
 
 Population 
 
 Coal production 
 
 i860 
 
 1.5 
 
 
 
 1890 
 
 2-5 
 
 25-5 
 
 854 
 
 1900 
 
 3-5 
 
 20.7 
 
 91.0 
 
 1910 
 
 5-5 
 
 21.0 
 
 86.0 
 
 * United States Geological Survey: The Production of Coal in the United 
 States, 1910, p. 51. 
 
 This is the unanimous testimony coming from all sections of the 
 country. See Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 23; vol. 
 7. pp. 145, 146, 156, 217, 220. 
 
 * The figures for the diagram are taken from the compilation in the 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 5, Table 5. 
 
 Mines and Quarries, 1902, p. 669, Table 6. United States Geological 
 
420 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The development of coal mining outside of Pennsylvania 
 from 1880 to 1889 was sufficient to have absorbed every old 
 employee who had been working in the bituminous coal 
 
 DIAGRAM XXII. 
 
 20 
 $0 
 
 so 
 
 30 
 
 20 
 JO 
 
 $0 
 
 g 
 
 SO 
 
 30 
 
 go 
 
 1 , 
 
 90 
 80 
 20 
 
 50 
 
 30 
 go 
 
 10 
 100 
 
 SO 
 eo 
 20 
 o 
 
 JO 00 
 CO 
 
 30 
 
 to 
 
 I 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 1 
 
 00 
 
 S 5 
 
 il 
 
 Si 
 
 00 
 
 1 
 
 0\ 
 
 CO 
 00 
 
 I 
 
 Penn. 
 
 All Other 
 
 States 
 
 Middle West 
 
 South and 
 Southwest 
 
 Penn. and 
 Middle West 
 
 xxn. 
 
 Number of persons employed in bituminous coal mines, 1880, 
 1889, and 1907 (thousands) 
 
 mines of Pennsylvania in 1880. The development of 
 mining in the South and Southwest since 1889 has been 
 sufficient to have furnished employment to every wage- 
 earner who had been at work in the bituminous coal mines 
 
 Survey: Production of Coal, 1910, p. 21. 
 vol. i., p. 24. 
 
 XIII. Census. Population , 
 
The Coal Miners 421 
 
 of Pennsylvania and the Middle West in 1889. At the 
 same time the additions since 1889 to the force employed 
 in the bituminous coal mines of Pennsylvania alone have 
 equaled the increase in the operating forces of the Southern 
 and Southwestern mines, while the additions to the number 
 of employees in the Middle West since 1889 have exceeded 
 the total number of the mine workers of Pennsylvania for 
 that year. This growth of the industry stimulated a great 
 deal of shifting of labor from one place to another. 
 
 The main inducement for experienced miners to migrate 
 westward was the greatejcjopportunity for advancement in 
 the rapidly developing coal mines of the new fields. The 
 proportion of supervisory or better-paid positions in an old 
 coal mine, like in any other establishment, is limited. The 
 opening of every new mine, however, creates new positions 
 for skilled and experienced miners. While the expansion 
 of mining operations in the older States offered many 
 opportunities for advancement to old employees, still in 
 no single concern could all the employees be raised to higher 
 positions at one time. The more ambitious, to whom the 
 road to promotion at their old places appeared too long, 
 sought better opportunities in new fields. Their places 
 had to be filled by new immigrants. There was no "dis- 
 placement " l of the old by the new employees; the Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans did not "inundate" the oldej: 
 employees, but merely filled the vacuum produced by the 
 continuous pumping out of the older employees. The 
 ultimate result of these migrations within the coal-mining 
 industry has been that "the largest portion of those remain- 
 ing, including the most efficient and progressive element, t 
 have, as a result of the expansion of the industry, secured \ 
 advancement to the more skilled and responsible positions." 2 / 
 
 The openings for the English-speaking mine workers were 
 not confined to mining. 
 
 1 The misuse of the word "displacement" in the Reports of the Immi- 
 gration Commission has been adverted to, in Chapter VII. 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 537. 
 

 422 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The period of development in coal mining and coke manufacturing 
 was also a period of great expansion in manufacturing industries . . . 
 so that for the intelligent and ambitious American, German, English, 
 Irish, or Scotch employee there were abundant opportunities to secure 
 more pleasant or better paid work in shops and factories near 
 home.* 
 
 Moreover, the growth of mining communities has created 
 Business opportunities for alert Americans and English- 
 speaking immigrants. An illustration is furnished by the 
 Borough of South Fork, Cambria County, Pennsylvania, 
 alias "Representative Community B," 2 where "the English- 
 speaking races seem to leave the mines as soon as they 
 accumulate earnings and to enter mercantile pursuits or 
 seek more remunerative or more pleasant work of other 
 kinds. The greater number of the business and professional 
 men in the town were formerly mine workers." 3 
 
 The Immigration Commission believes that this advance- 
 ment is "probably without direct connection with recent 
 ^immigration." 4 This is, however, a mistaken view. 
 ..t^'V Bituminous coal is practically the only product of the 
 locality." 5 It is owing only to "the opening of the new 
 mines and the extension of the old ones" 6 that the popu- 
 > lation of the "representative community" has grown from 
 1295 in 1890 to 2635 in 1900 and to 4592 in 1910. Two_ 
 'thirds of this increase were due to immigration, not counting 
 \the native-born children of immigrants. 7 And it is ob- 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, p. 335. The quotatio* relates 
 to Pennsylvania, but the same is true of the United States in general. 
 
 a The description of that community contains nothing of a confidential 
 nature that would warrant the withholding of its name from the public 
 in an official report. Moreover, the disguise is too thin to be effective: 
 there is only one incorporated place in the State of Pennsylvania that 
 had a population of 2635 in 1900 (XIII. Census: Population, vol. in' 
 P- 558). 
 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 563. See also 
 
 p -^- \M>id., P . 563. 
 
 Ibid., p. 532. 6 ^d., p. 563. 
 
 7 In 1900 the total number of foreign-born in the borough was 587; 
 in 1908 it was estimated at 1900. Ibid., p. 533. 
 
The Coal Miners 423 
 
 viously ^^^aSE^S^^LS^^^^-^f-^ borough that 
 has made room for more professional and business men. 
 
 Speaking generally, the "employees displaced as miners " 
 could not "have gone into manufacturing plants and shops 
 . . . into street railways and trolley service, or into business 
 for themselves," 1 had not the recent immigrants furnished 
 the labor to do the disagreeable and dangerous work in the 
 manufacturing plants and mines and the passengers to 
 ride on the trolley cars. 
 
 "The displaced employees did not better their economic 
 condition," however, in the Middle West says the Immi- 
 gration Commission. The "subsequent history of the 
 old employees" in that section is recited as follows: 
 
 No extensive data are available as to the subsequent history of the 
 pioneer miners in the Middle West who were displaced by the recent 
 immigrant. It is well known, and has already been pointed out, that 
 many of them advanced in the industrial scale, becoming foremen and 
 attaining other responsible positions. It has also been mentioned that 
 a large number abandoned the occupation of miner for positions as day 
 or shift men. Many also migrated and located in other sections of the 
 Middle West where hand mining continued to be followed, and many 
 also moved to other coal-fields, principally to Kansas and Oklahoma, 
 in the Southwest. The reports from several communities also show that 
 many of the former miners who left the industry entirely . . . entered 
 mercantile, clerical, mechanical, and other lines of work. The reports 
 further unite in the statement, however, that the displaced employees 
 did not better their economic condition. 3 
 
 There are irreconcilable contradictions in this "history." C*^ 1 
 It seems inconceivable that those of the "displaced" pick 
 miners who "advanced in the industrial scale, becoming 
 foremen and attaining other .responsible positions" (there 
 are alleged to have been "many of them"), "did not better ^- 
 their economic condition." It is contrary to common 
 experience that the "displaced" miners "who left the in- 
 dustry" to enter mercantile or mechanical lines of work 
 should not be earning more as business men or mechanics 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 426. 
 Ibid., p. 668. 
 
424 Immigration and Labor 
 
 than they had been earning with pick and shovel inside 
 of a coal mine. The "data . . . as to the subsequent 
 history of the pioneer miners" are admittedly scarce. 
 The loose "statement" of the anonymous "reports" is 
 clearly sheer hearsay, which deserves no place in an official 
 report. 
 
 The Immigration Commission attaches undue importance 
 to the social prejudice against "a Hunkey's job," which it 
 considers "one of the strongest forces toward the displace- 
 ment of the older employees either from the industry or 
 
 .v'from certain occupations within the industry." 1 The 
 Commission mistakes here cause for effect. The contempt 
 for " a Hunkey's job " did not exist so long as the bulk of the 
 English-speaking operatives were employed on that grade 
 of work. Yet, then as now, the "tendency" on the part 
 of the native American "to abandon the occupation of 
 coal digging and to enter the better class of positions about 
 the mines" must have been "decidedly marked," 2 when- 
 ever an opportunity presented itself. ) We further learn that^ 
 "the exodus of former operatives from the industry" was 
 stimulated by "the fact that there were opportunities to 
 secure work whichjpaid as well or better than mining, that 
 this worlTwas often more agreeable and less dangerous." 3 
 It was only after their~elevation (or "displacement," as 
 the Commission would have it) from the ranks of coal 
 diggers to the more exalted station of mine bosses and street 
 car conductors that they began to look *down upon those 
 who had succeeded them. This caste feeling is far too 
 general in all climes and conditions of life to be classed 
 </ among the effects of "recent immigration." 
 
 Still more strained is the argument that the recent 
 
 j, immigration "is preventing them [the English-speaking 
 miners] from allowing their children to enter the industry. 
 The prosperous miner educates his children for softer- 
 handed work and they have t^mpve away from Community 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 426. 
 
 'Ibid., vol. 7, p. 221. * Ibid., vol. 6, p. 335 
 
The Coal Miners 425 
 
 A [Shenandoah, Pa.] to find it. The well-to-do store- 
 keeper and the professional man moves away to find a 
 more suitable environment for his growing children." 1 
 This statement implies that but for the recent immigrant, 
 a prosperous American father, who has the means to educate 
 his son for "softer-handed work/' would allow him to do 
 the disagreeable and dangerous work of a coal miner. Could 
 a "well-to-do storekeeper" or a professional man find 
 better opportunities for his son in a coal-mining town like 
 Y' Shenandoah with a population of 25,000, were all the coal 
 miners men of pure Anglo-Saxon blood ? 
 
 The increasing consumption of coal by the expanding 
 American industries which has drawn to pur coal mines the 
 great masses of Southern and Eastem,European immigrants, 
 has also stimulated the introduction of mining machinery. ^ 
 The tendency of machinery is to replace the skilled miner 
 by the unskilled laborer. The old American, English, 
 Welsh, and Irish miners were pick miners. The introduc- 
 tion of mining machines, though gradual, must have dis- 
 placed many of them and forced them to seek employment 
 elsewhere. To be sure, the expansion of the coal-mining 
 industry has been so rapid that the displaced pick miners 
 soon found more remunerative employment as machine 
 runners or in supervisory capacities. But this industrial 
 transformation did not proceed without social waste and 
 friction. When a new labor-saving machine is introduced, 
 no provision is made for the men whose labor is to be 
 dispensed with. The time, however short, spent in search 
 of other employment may cause them hardship and anxiety. 
 Meanwhile, they see their places taken by aliens speaking 
 a foreign tongue. The impression is created that it is these 
 unskilled foreigners who have displaced the English-speak- 
 ing miners. The pick miners, like labor in general, opposed 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 16, p. 66 1. Community 
 A is situated in Schuylkill County, Pa., and can be identified by the 
 number of its inhabitants given on p. 663 (XIII. Census: Population, 
 vol. iii., p. 558). 
 
426 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the introduction of machinery. 1 It_ naturally appeared to 
 them that without the recent immigrants who were willing 
 
 ^to work at the machines the introduction of mining ma- 
 chinery would have been impossible. These views* o the 
 English-speaking miners have found their way into the 
 reports of the Industrial Commission 2 and of the Immigra- 
 tion Commission. 3 Mine operators who certainly know 
 the economic advantage of the use of machinery have 
 
 /assumed an apologetic attitude by throwing the blame upon 
 
 y the immigrant, whose lack of "skill" makes the use of 
 machinery imperative. 4 The truth is that a team of in- 
 experienced, unskilled Slavs working under one machine 
 
 ^runner are more efficient than an equal number of skilled 
 and experienced English-speaking pick miners. 
 
 The comparative efficiency of pick and machine mining 
 appears from the following calculation based on the report 
 of the Ohio Chief Inspector of Mines for 1909. To every 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 662. 
 
 a Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. xxxiv. 
 
 3 "To some extent, the employment of the recent immigrant may 
 have stimulated the use of mining machinery, inasmuch as this machinery 
 renders it possible to employ in large numbers inexperienced and un- 
 trained men* Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, pp. 423, 
 424. Elsewhere, under the significant caption "Deterioration of 
 working conditions and methods caused by employment of recent 
 immigrants," the Commission quotes the opinions of "the miners and 
 union officials," who criticize the operators, "who, to fill abnormal 
 demands for coal, employed inexperienced immigrants in such large 
 numbers that it was impossible to teach them to mine by approved 
 ^methods. . . . The statement is then made by the old employee that 
 this state of affairs . . . leads to the introduction of machines. " 
 Ibid., p. 670. 
 
 * "The operators claim that, owing to the large percentage of immi- 
 grants at work in the mines who are unskilled, they are forced to use 
 machines in order to maintain a good quality of coal, because where no 
 machines are used the recent immigrants 'shoot the coal off the solid* 
 instead of properly undercutting it, jind, with excessive charges of 
 powder, they thus produce a much larger percentage of slack coal than 
 is produced when undercutting is done with the machine or by hand. " 
 Ibid., p. 650. 
 
The Coal Miners 427 
 
 five pick miners there was employed one inside day hand. 
 An average day's work per pick miner was 2.2 tons of lump 
 coal, or 3.3 tons "run of mine." The average daily pro- 
 duction per inside man was accordingly 1.8 tons of lump 
 coal or 2.7 tons "run of mine." In machine mining there 
 were on an average eight loaders, drillers, and shooters to 
 each runner, and two other inside day hands to one runner. 
 The average quantity cut by each machine runner per day 
 was twenty-nine tons of lump coal or forty-three tons "run 
 of mine." The average daily production per inside hand 
 was 2.6 tons of lump coal or 3.9 tons "run of mine." 1 
 The margin in favor of machine mining was 0.8 tons of 
 lump, or 1.2 tons "run of mine" per inside man, which was 
 equivalent to a saviiiL_of 30 per cent. Moreover, with 
 pick mining, ten out of every twelve inside men were skilled 
 miners, whereas with machine mining only one in every 
 eleven was a skilled man and the other ten were semi- 
 skilled day men or unskilled coal loaders. The average 
 price per ton paid to contract-miners is accordingly lower 
 for machine mining than for pick mining. In Illinois the 
 margin varied in 1901-1911 from 11.3 to 16.9 cents per 
 ton. 2 The saving resulting from machine mining is esti- 
 mated by an authority as follows: 
 
 At a mine producing 1000 tons per day and having a 15 cent margin 
 in favor of machine mining, the gross saving would be about $150 a day, 
 or $30,000 per year of 200 days. . . . The $30,000 saving will pay for 
 the machine plant, installation, and cost of maintenance, as well as inter- 
 est and depreciation, in about one year's time. The advantages of coal 
 cutting are: (i) v an increased percentage of large coal; (2) 'the coal is 
 mined in a firmer and better condition; (3) a more regular line of face is 
 obtained, leading to more systematic timbering; (4) increased safety 
 conditions for the miner; (5) thin seams can be profitably mined; (6) 
 increased output; and (7) fewer explosives are required for getting down 
 the coal. 3 
 
 1 Thirty- Fifth Annual Report of the Chief Inspector of Mines, Ohio, pp. 
 90, 93. 94, 99, ioo. 
 
 * Illinois Coal Report, 1911, p. 121. 
 
 *Coal and Coke, by Floyd W. Parsons, "The Mirieral Industry," 
 1909, pp. 143, 144. 
 
428 Immigration and Labor 
 
 jr To imagine that the opposition of the English-speaking 
 'miners could have forced the mine operators to waive these 
 savings, is to assume that without Slav and Italian immi- 
 gration the laws of modern industrial evolution would have 
 been suspended in the United States. 
 
 Statistics show that machine mining has made great 
 progress in States with a small percentage of Southern and 
 Eastern European coal miners and has been lagging behind 
 / in States with a large percentage of Southern and Eastern 
 European coal miners. This fact stands out conspicuously 
 in Diagram XXIII. 1 In 1900, the greatest progress of 
 machine mining was reported from Ohio, while Vest Vir- 
 ginia was the most backward State, though the proportion 
 of Southern and Eastern European miners in both States 
 was the same. More than four fifths of the machine 
 product of Ohio must have been mined by English-speaking 
 men. The second rank in the order of the percentages of 
 machine-mined coal was held by Kentucky, where the 
 proportion of Southern and Eastern European miners was 
 negligible. In Indiana likewise more than four fifths of all 
 machine-mined coal was produced by English-speaking 
 mine workers. On the other hand, Pennsylvania had four 
 times as many Slavs, Italians, etc., working in coal mines as 
 Ohio, yet machine mining was less advanced in Pennsyl- 
 vania than in Ohio. In Pennsylvania and Illinois the 
 percentage of machine-mined coal was greater than the 
 percentage of Southern and Eastern European miners. 
 Bearing in mind the greater average production per man 
 where mining is done by machines, it can be clearly seen 
 that a great deal of pick mining in those two States must 
 have been done by Southern and Eastern Europeans. The 
 occupation statistics of the census of 1910 have as yet not 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XXVI. The production of bituminous coal 
 in the States shown in the diagram amounted in 1910 to 80 per cent of the 
 total for the United States, and their aggregate production of machine- 
 mined coal for the ten-year period 1900-1909 to 90 per cent of the total 
 output of machine-mined coal in the United States. 
 
DIAGRAM XXIII. 
 
 o 10 ao 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 
 
 I I I LI I I I M I I I M I I M I I I I I I I I I I I M I J | I | | | | | | | I I \ 
 
 KY. 
 
 IND. 
 
 v////^//s//////Y//////// 
 ll KX 
 
 W.VA. 
 
 i I I I I I I I M I I I I | | | | | | I 
 o 10 20 30 40 
 
 QrS.*.CV*OPAN3TQPQPUL*riOH 1910 
 
 Per cent of bituminous coal mined by machine, 1900 and 
 
 1910, compared with per cent ratio of Southern and East- 
 
 ern European miners to all miners, 1900; and with per 
 
 cent ratio of Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 
 to the total population, 1910, for the prin- 
 
 cipal States. 
 
430 Immigration and Labor 
 
 been published. Still for the purposes of the present com- 
 parison a fairly accurate index of the employment of 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans in the mines is furnished 
 by the ratio of each nationality to the total population of 
 the State for iQio. 1 The order of the States, according to 
 the proportion of machine-mined coal, has changed since 
 1900: Pennsylvania has been outranked by Indiana and 
 Illinois by West Virginia. It will be observed that in each 
 
 t vof these changes the State with the lower proportion of 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans exhibits greater progress 
 
 ^ of machine mining. Again, we find Ohio in the lead, while 
 Pennsylvania with twice as many Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans reports a little over one half as much machine- 
 mined coal. The second rank according to the progress of 
 machine mining is held by Kentucky, where the proportion 
 of Southern and Eastern Europeans is negligible, whereas 
 ^Illinois with almost as many Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans in proportion as Pennsylvania is at the bottom of the 
 scale. West Virginia, which had been far behind Pennsyl- 
 vania in 1900 with regard to the introdugion of machinery, 
 in 1910 stood even with Pennsylvania. For these two 
 States we find in the report of the Immigration Commission 
 the percentage of Southern and Eastern Europeans em- 
 ployed in the coal mines in 1908, viz., in Pennsylvania, 64.3 
 per cent ; in West Virginia, 28.9 per cent. * The proportion of 
 machine-mined coal was 45 per cent in each State. If the 
 introduction of machinery were stimulated by immigration, 
 it might be expected that the percentage of machine-mined 
 coal in Pennsylvania would be twice as high as in West 
 Virginia. Assuming that in West Virginia all unskilled 
 labor connected with machine mining was done by recent 
 immigrants and negroes, it can be seen at a glance that in 
 
 ^the mines of Pennsylvania where the Southern and Eastern 
 
 1 This can be clearly seen from a_ comparison of the three series of 
 percentages of Southern and Eastern Europeans in Table XXVI of 
 the Appendix. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, Tables 140 and 143. 
 
The Coal Miners 431 
 
 Europeans predominate, a large proportion of them must 
 have been employed at pick mining. x 
 
 There are many factors of a local character, such as rail- 
 way freights, market conditions, the nature of the coal -? 
 deposit, etc., which may produce variations in the per- / 
 centage of machine-mined coal for individual States. A 
 definite tendency, however, becomes apparent if the six 
 States are combined into two groups: (i) Ohio, Kentucky, 
 and Indiana, and (2) Pennsylvania, West Virginia, and 
 Illinois. In the first group the percentage of machine- 
 mined coal for 1910 was higher than in the second group. 
 In 1900, Ohio was in advance of Pennsylvania, while Ken- 
 tucky and Indiana were in advance of Illinois and West 
 Virginia; taken as a whole, the first group had a larger 
 percentage of machine-mined coal than the second. At the 
 same time the proportion of Southern and Eastern Euro- 
 peans was larger in the second group, taken as a whole, than 
 in the first. In 1900, as well as in 1910, Pennsylvania had 
 a higher percentage than Ohio, West Virginia, and Illinois. 
 
 On the whole, then, it seems, the percentage of machine- ^r 
 mined coal is higher in that group which has the lower 
 percentage of recent immigrants. This conclusion is in 
 accord with economic conditions : where the supply of labor 
 grows slowly, resort must be had to machinery to satisfy 
 the rapidly growing demand for coal. 
 
 1 The proportion of Southern and Eastern European miners employed 
 at machine and pick mining can be calculated as follows: An allowance 
 of 30 per cent must be made for the saving of labor by machinery. Of a 
 team of nine working at a mining machine, one, the runner, is an English- 
 speaking miner. Exclusive of the runners, the mining of 45 per cent of 
 the output required the services of (!) 45 (0.70) -=28 per cent of all mine 
 workers. The proportion of Southern and Eastern Europeans being 
 65 per cent of the total employed, there was a surplus of 37 per cent 
 equal to 37 -*- 65 * 57 per cent of all Southern and Eastern Europeans, for 
 whom there was no place at machine mining. In this calculation no 
 account is taken of the English-speaking semi-skilled men employed at 
 machine mining. If an allowance be made for them, the percentage ot 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans who could not have been utilized at 
 machine mining would be still larger. 
 
432 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The Immigration Commission states that in every section 
 of the country a period in the development of the coal- 
 i/mining industry was_reached when^ the supply of labor, 
 rst,"~of native Americans, and later of English-speaking 
 immigrants, became inadequate " to satisfy the demand and 
 r recourse was necessarily had by the mining operators to 
 immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe. Without 
 . the employment of mine workers drawn from this class of 
 JK immigrants, the growth in the bituminous mining industry 
 f would have been impossible." 1 At the same time the 
 Immigration Commission believes that one of the effects 
 of recent immigration, "which seems to be well established, 
 %r is the decrease of the average number of working days 
 I annually "avaflaHte'To'the' older employee." 2 Thejncon- 
 fJJae_^ apparently escaped the 
 
 attention of the Commission. The evidence by which 
 the last-quoted statement is "established" is not given in 
 the report of the Commission, beyond the bare " allegation " 
 of "the older miners" of Illinois that "even under normal 
 industrial conditions there are two miners for every place 
 that offers steady work for one miner. "J 
 
 The fact is, as noted by the Commission, that coal mining 
 is a seasonal trade. 3 The demand is greatest in the fall 
 and winter, and declines with warm weather. The mine 
 operators run their mines in accordance with market 
 Conditions, as can be seen from Diagram XXIV. 4 In this 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 423. See also pp. 
 23, 24, 260, 661 ; vol. 7, pp. 216-217; in the South "the demand for labor 
 has outgrown the supply"; vol. 16, pp. 592, 655. 
 
 'Ibid., vol. 6, p. 668. s Ibid., vol. 6, pp. 97, 668. 
 
 Based on Thirteenth Annual Coal Report, Illinois, 1911, pp. 54-55. 
 
 JThe Commission quotes, in the same connection (vol vi., p. 669), 
 "the conviction on the part of natives that a preference is shown for the 
 immigrants in the distribution of work. " If the statistics of the Immi- 
 gration Commission may be trusted, they disprove this conviction on 
 the part of the natives. The figures which are given in Table 343 (p. 
 649) of the same volume, relate to the Middle West, where that "con- 
 viction" is said to prevail. The native and Southern and Eastern 
 
The Coal Miners 
 
 DIAGRAM XXIV. 
 
 433 
 
 Tons 
 
 00,0001 
 _ 7600,000 
 _ 7200,000 
 . 6,500,000 
 _ 6J*00,000 
 
 op.ooq 
 
 600.000 
 200.000 
 _4800000 
 .440QOOC 
 
 JULY AUG. SEP. OCT. NOV. DEC. JAN. FEB. MAR. APR. MAY JUNE 
 
 XXIV. Coal production by months in Illinois, 1906-1910. 
 
 European miners were distributed by the number of months worked 
 in 1907 as follows: 
 
 
 Per ce 
 
 at working 
 
 Months 
 
 Native- 
 born 
 
 Italians, Lithuanians, 
 and Poles 
 
 J2 . 
 
 182 
 
 I 1 
 
 
 68.2 
 
 AQ 7 
 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 O67 
 
 
 
 
 It must be understood, however, that these statistics are of as little 
 value as the opinions of the few "old miners" quoted by the Immigra- 
 tion Commission. The total number of native miners included in its 
 "study of households" was only 371 for all bituminous mines in the 
 United States and 79 for all anthracite mines. (Ibid., vol. 6, p. 97; 
 vol. 16, p. 619.) The number is too small to serve as a basis for any 
 
434 Immigration and Labor 
 
 respect the mine operators do not differ from other entre- 
 preneurs. There is nothing to prevent a manufacturer of 
 awnings from distributing the work of his establishment 
 evenly over the whole year; yet he prefers to manufacture 
 them when there is an immediate demand for them. An 
 even distribution of mining operations over the whole 
 year would necessitate an outlay for wages and supplies, 
 and a permanent investment for additional storage facilities. 
 /Such an additional investment would be prohibitive for 
 \many of the smaller operators, while the larger ones could 
 
 v gain no advantage from it, since competition would not 
 permit them to shift the interest to the consumer. 
 
 So long as the mines run full time at one season and part 
 time at others, unemployment is inevitable. The difference 
 between coal mining and other industries is only that, 
 instead of discharging a portion of the force and keeping 
 the rest fully employed, the coal operator retains the full 
 
 v force in his employ, but keeps them all on part time.- There 
 are several economic reasons for this system. In the first 
 place the operator wants to keep his full force always ready 
 on call. Coal mines are, as a rule, not located in great 
 urban" centres where there is at all times an available 
 supply of men seeking employment. Chief among the 
 contributory causes is the real estate interest of the mining 
 company. Every operator who opens a new mine in an 
 unsettled locality must provide houses for his employees. 
 After having invested in workmen's dwellings, the mine 
 operator is interested in keeping them occupied. To lay 
 off a part of his employees during the summer months would 
 involve a loss of rent, as they would leave in order to seek 
 employment elsewhere. Where the mining company is also 
 running a general store for its employees, it wants to retain 
 
 conclusions. The greatest variation between the native and foreign- 
 born appears in the percentage of bituminous coal miners employed 
 six months and over, viz., 82.2 for the native and 88.8 for the foreign- 
 bora (ibid., vol. 6, p. 97). The difference of 6.6 per cent represents 
 only twenty-three native workers scattered all over the United States. 
 
The Coal Miners 435 
 
 them as customers. While the mine operators are guided 
 in their policy by business considerations, rather than by 
 philanthropy, the mine workers as a class have no ground 
 for complaint against this policy, so long as coal mining 
 remains a seasonal trade. The other alternative would be 
 
 v full employment for some and complete idleness and want 
 for the others. 
 
 Inasmuch as the demand for coal fluctuates from year 
 
 Vto year, it is inevitable that when the demand suffers a 
 temporary decline, there should not be enough work to 
 give full time employment to all the men who were needed 
 during the previous season of maximum activity. An 
 illustration of these fluctuations can be seen in Diagram 
 XXIV. This is the basis of the complaint of the miners 
 that too rapid a pace of development eventually pleads to 
 undef-employment. x These cyclical variations, however, 
 ,are not peculiar to coal mining alone, but are incidents of 
 the modern industrial development in all lines of production. 
 In fact the fluctuations in the demand for coal are merely 
 the reflections of the fluctuations in the industrial field as 
 a whole. That they are not the product of immigration, 
 but, on the contrary, they run parallel with the fluctuations 
 of immigration, has been shown in Chapter VI. (See Dia- 
 gram X.) 
 
 The fluctuating character of the coal-mining industry 
 produces a migratory type of mine worker. To the old 
 employee, however, who is permanently working at one 
 mine, these migratory applicants for work naturally appear 
 as one of the causes of fluctuation in the opportunities for 
 employment. The Immigration Commission is voicing 
 the complaint of "the older employee to the effect that the 
 
 k recent immigrants being largely unmarried and at the same 
 
 f time, migratory in their habits, move readily from one 
 locality to another, always seeking the community where 
 there is a demand for labor and thus cause^in .numerous 
 instances, an oversupply of labor, which reacts to the injury 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 669. 
 
436 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the employees permanently working and living in the 
 locality affected." 1 The recent immigrants accordingly 
 
 ^cause an oversupply of labor by seeking a place "where 
 there is a demand for labor, " whereas if they stayed where 
 there is no demand for their labor there would supposedly 
 be no oversupply of labor. But what of "the older em- 
 ployees" who are permanently living in the communities 
 where there is no demand for the labor of the migratory 
 immigrants? Might they not regard it as an "injury" 
 to themselves if the immigrants resolved to abandon their 
 migratory habits and stay where there is no demand for 
 them? The oldest inhabitants of a mining town are 
 naturally inclined to view every question from the angle of 
 their local interests. But their criterion need not be gener- 
 ally accepted as representative of the interests of labor at 
 large. 
 /Complaints have often been made that, apart from the 
 
 g/fluctuations in the demand for coal, under-employment 
 
 \in the anthracite mines is the result of a deliberate 
 pn the part of the operators to employ a larger force than 
 might be required when the mines run at full capacity. 2 
 There was a good foundation for this complaint in the past. 
 In the '70*8, after the breakdown of the union of anthracite 
 coal miners, the coal companies engaged a larger force 
 which resulted in the curtailment of the average production 
 per man. This was, however, in the days of British, Irish, 
 and German immigration. During the last ten years, i. e., 
 
 V since the beginning of the new immigration, the average 
 annual production per man has been fast increasing. 
 
 The following table shows an increase of the average 
 annual number employed from 44,000 in 1870-1874 to 
 68,000 in 1875-1879, while the average annual output 
 increased only 10 per cent. The expansion of the busi- 
 ness obviously did not call for an increase of 55 per cent 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission^ vol. 6, p. 669. 
 a Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., p. 405. Peter Roberts, 
 The Anthracite Coal Industry, pp. 126-127. 
 
The Coal Miners 
 
 437 
 
 in the number of employees. As a result the average 
 tonnage per emplgyeejieclined 28 per cent. It rose again 
 during the first half of the '8o's still remaining 20 per cent 
 
 TABLE 126. 
 
 NUMBER OF WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED IN ANTHRACITE COAL MINES, 
 AND PRODUCTION OF COAL BY FIVE-YEAR PERIODS, 1870-1909. 
 
 
 
 Average annual production 2 
 
 
 Average annual 
 
 (long tons) 
 
 Period 
 
 
 
 
 (thousands) 
 
 Total millions 
 
 Per employee 
 
 1870-1874 
 1875-1879 
 
 n 
 
 2O 
 22 
 
 448 
 322 
 
 1880-1884 
 
 85 
 
 31 
 
 361 
 
 1885-1889 
 
 no 
 
 38 
 
 342 
 
 1890-1894 
 
 130 
 
 4 6 
 
 350 
 
 1895-1899 
 
 145 
 
 50 
 
 343 
 
 1900-1904 
 
 151 
 
 56 
 
 372 
 
 1905-1909 
 
 171 
 
 71 
 
 417 
 
 below the average of 1870-1874. It declined again during 
 the second half of the '8o's and remained stationary until 
 1900. Since that time a marked improvement is notice- 
 able. The annual average per employee in 1900-1904 was 
 higher than in 1880-1884, and in 1905-1909 it came within 
 7 per cent of the average of 1870-1874. If the comparison 
 is carried back to the first half of the *8o's, when the English- 
 speaking mine workers were given more days per man than 
 ever since the defeat of the strike of 1875 up to 1900, it 
 appears that in 1905-1909, during the height of Southern 
 and Eastern European immigration, the average mine 
 worker was given 15.5 per cent more work than at the time 
 the Slav and Italian employees in the anthracite 
 mines were a negligible quantity. This means that the 
 
 See Appendix, Table XXVIII. 
 
 3 Computed from the Report of the United States Geological Survey: 
 The Production of Coal, 1910, pp. 189-190. 
 
438 Immigration and Labor 
 
 recent immigrant labor supply has been smaller in propor- 
 tion to the demagdjorjaborjnjg^ the supply 
 of mine workers from Northern and Western Europe thirty 
 years ago. 
 
 As stated above, the reports of the Immigration Com- 
 mission for every district concur in that the native labor 
 '/supply wasjnadequate ioj:Jiie._QperatiQn. of the mines_f rom 
 the very beginning, that the supply of immigrants from the 
 -r, ^British Isles and Germany soon also proved insufficient, 
 **/ Jand that the mine operators from remoter districts were 
 / bidding in the Eastern labor market for immigrants of 
 ^ every nationality willing to work in the Western mines. 
 If it is true that the demand for labor exceeded the avail- 
 able supply, it necessarily follows that wages must have 
 ( risen. That such has been the fact is not denied by the 
 Immigration Commission. It s'eeks, however, to qualify 
 it in accordance with its preconceived ideas about the 
 immigrant. We are told that in Pennsylvania "the com- 
 panies were not compelled as a result of agitation or protest 
 to increase wages ... in order to hold the native and 
 former workmen, since they were able to fill their places 
 . . . with recent immigrants who were content with the 
 wages . . . which prevailed in the bituminous regions. 
 // is true that wages have risen in the industry, but as a rule 
 only to meet the competition of other industries which use 
 unskilled labor." 1 
 
 . Thus "the companies were not compelled ... to 
 *pncrease wages," because the recent immigrants "were 
 ^{content" with the prevailing wages, and yet somehow 
 wages have risen. " It might be inferred that the com- 
 panies voluntarily increased wages though the recent 
 immigrants did not ask for it, were it not for the concluding 
 statement that the raise was made " to meet the competition 
 of other industries which use unskilled labor. " Apparently 
 then in those "other industries" wages were also raised, 
 and the recent immigrants, though "content" with lower 
 1 Reports oj the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, p. 424. 
 
The Coal Miners 439 
 
 wages in coal mines, were equally content to quit the mines 
 
 and accept higher wages in other industries. The most 
 
 important of those industries in Pennsylvania is the iron 
 
 and steel industry, in which most of the unskilled laborers 
 
 are also recent immigrants. So it would seem that in order 
 
 to hold these new employees the iron and steel companies 
 
 , were compelled to increase wages, and the coal companies 
 
 - in order to hold their own recent immigrants had to follow 
 
 suit. 
 
 An index of the increase in the earnings of the Pennsyl- 
 vania coal miners since the beginning of the "new immigra- 
 tion" is furnished by the average wages per ton in the an- 
 thracite coal mines at the XI. and XIII. Censuses, which 
 increased from 83 cents in 1889 to $1.14 in 1909, i. e., 37.3 
 per cent. At the same time the progress in the use of 
 mechanical power raised the average output per wage- 
 earner. 1 
 
 In the unionized bituminous coal mines of the Pitts- 
 burgh district the scale is agreed upon at joint conferences 
 held biennially since 1898 between the operators and the 
 United Mine Workers. This is the period of the great 
 influx of Southern and Eastern Europeans into the coal 
 mines of the Pittsburgh district. Table 127 shows sub- 
 stantial increases^kr the scale for undercutting by machine 
 and day-occupations, in which English-speaking mine 
 workers are employed, as well as for loading which is 
 the work of Southern and Eastern Europeans, and for 
 pick mining, at which men of all races are employed. In 
 4 other words, the Southern and Eastern Europeans have 
 had the same measure of success in bargaining for wages as 
 the English-speaking employees. 
 
 While wages have increased, the hours of labor have 
 been reduced from ten to eight. Moreover, "many kinds 
 of work, such as entry cutting, room turning, removing 
 clay, etc., for which formerly nothing was paid, now have 
 a regular scale. This 'dead work/ in a mine employing 
 
 1 XIII. Census, vol. xi., Mines and Quarries, pp. 188, 189. 
 
 (j 
 
440 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 one hundred and fifty men, would add about $i .50 per week 
 to the wages of each of them. It means an addition of 
 about ten per cent to a miner's pay. " x 
 
 TABLE 127. 
 
 UNION SCALE OF WAGES IN BITUMINOUS COAL MINES, 1898-1908. a 
 
 Occupation 
 
 1898-1900 
 
 1906-1908 
 
 Increase 
 per cent 
 
 
 Per ton 
 $0.66 
 
 Per ton 
 $0.90 
 
 36.4 
 
 Air Machines. 
 Undercutting in rooms 
 
 .125 
 
 .1708 
 
 36.6 
 
 
 f 
 .36 
 
 .456 
 
 26.7 
 
 Electric Machines. 
 Undercutting . . 
 
 .08 
 
 .11 
 
 37.5 
 
 Loading 
 
 .36 
 
 47 
 
 3O.6 
 
 Inside Day Work. 
 Tracklayers, bottom cagers, drivers, 
 trip riders, water and machine 
 haulers, and timbermen 
 
 Per day 
 
 I.QO 
 
 Per day 
 2.56 
 
 4O.O 
 
 Pi pemen for compressed air plants. . . 
 All other inside labor 
 
 1.84 
 1.75 
 
 2.50 
 
 2.-*6 
 
 30-4 
 74.0 
 
 Trappers (boys) 
 
 .75 
 
 I.I-z 
 
 SO.7 
 
 
 
 
 
 The advances in the scale of wages paid to various 
 classes of employees in non-unionized mines of Pennsyl- 
 vania 3 are shown in Table 128, condensed from the report 
 of the Immigration Commission. 
 
 J Wages for all grades of employment have increased 
 
 since 1895. The rate of increase for common laborers, 
 
 , who are practically all Southern and Eastern Europeans, 
 
 v is higher than for machine bosses, who are Americans or 
 
 English-speaking foreigners. 
 
 The report of the Immigration Commission contains 
 statistics of average daily earnings for 79,575 mine workers 
 classified by race and nativity. As there is no classification 
 of each racial group by occupation, the elaborate averages 
 
 1 Leiserson, loc. cit. t p. 319. Ibid., p. 320. 
 
 3 That the mines are non-unionized appears from the fact that they 
 are running on a ten-hour basis. 
 
The Coal Miners 
 
 441 
 
 TABLE 128. 
 
 WAGE SCALE OF EMPLOYEES IN THE COAL MINES OF ONE STEEL COMPANY 
 IN PENNSYLVANIA, 1 895-1908. x 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Daily wages 
 
 Increase per 
 cent 
 
 1895 
 
 1908 
 
 Machine boss . . 
 
 $2.50 
 53 
 50 
 
 .42 
 
 31 
 71 
 
 75 
 55 
 .62 
 
 25 
 25 
 
 .21 
 .20 
 
 .07 
 25 
 
 3 
 
 .06 
 
 .00 
 
 .70 
 
 $3.20 
 2.65 
 2.50 
 2.50 
 
 2.40 
 
 2.40 
 2.40 
 2.25 
 
 2.2O 
 2.IO 
 2.OO 
 1-95 
 
 l.8o 
 1-55 
 145 
 145 
 1-35 
 
 1.20 
 .90 
 
 28.O 
 66.7 
 
 66.7 
 76.1 
 83.2 
 404 
 38.2 
 45-2 
 35-8 
 68.0 
 60.0 
 61.2 
 50.0 
 
 44-9 
 16.0 
 40.8 
 27.4 
 
 2O.O 
 28.6 
 
 Boss driver 
 
 Team driver 
 
 
 
 Sheer (mule) 
 
 Motorman 
 
 Trip rider 
 
 
 
 Carpenter 
 
 Coupler .... 
 
 Tipple engineer 
 
 Tipple man 
 
 Switchman 
 
 
 Oiler (dilly road) 
 
 Patcher 
 
 Traooer (bov) . 
 
 
 and per 1000 ratios computed from "80 or more males 
 reporting," are of no value for comparative purposes. 
 The fact that the Mexican earns $2.44 per day, whereas 
 the American of native parentage earns only $2.3i, 2 does 
 not mean that the Mexican has a higher standard of living 
 and therefore " insists" upon a higher wage, whereas the 
 American, with his lower standard of living, is "content " to 
 accept a lower wage._\The higher average of the Mexican 
 "X fs simply the result of a different distribution of the Mexicans 
 by locality and grade of work. A selection of race groups 
 graded according to percentage earning each specified 
 amount per day is presented in Table 129. It clearly 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, Table 322. 
 3 Ibid., vol. 6, p, 50. 
 
442 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 shows that the immigrants from Southern and Eastern 
 - Europe are often earning more than native Americans of 
 native stock and English-speaking immigrants. 
 
 TABLE 129. 
 
 PER CENT OF ADULT BITUMINOUS COAL MINE WORKERS OF SELECTED 
 RACES EARNING EACH SPECIFIED AMOUNT PER DAY, BY LOCALITY. x 
 
 Earning $2.00 per day and over. 
 
 Earning $3.00 per day and over. 
 
 Rank 
 
 Locality and race 
 
 Per 
 
 cent 
 
 Rank 
 
 Locality and race 
 
 Per 
 cent 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 4 
 5 
 6 
 
 8 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 4 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 4 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 Middle West: 
 Russian 
 
 95-0 
 94-3 
 90.8 
 89.1 
 
 87.2 
 86.2 
 84-3 
 83.7 
 
 76.5 
 76.4 
 
 73-3 
 70.1 
 
 82.9 
 
 73-1 
 67.9 
 65.8 
 
 97.2 
 96.1 
 
 I 
 2 
 
 3 
 4 
 5 
 6 
 
 8 7 
 9 
 
 10 
 
 i 
 
 2 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 I 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 4 
 
 Middle West: 
 Croatian .... 
 
 69.9 
 46.3 
 
 45-0 
 41.7 
 37-9 
 36.9 
 31-3 
 27.4 
 26.2 
 25.1 
 
 13-5 
 
 7-7 
 
 19.4 
 12.9 
 
 56.8 
 38.3 
 31-6 
 18.9 
 
 Croatian 
 
 
 South Italian 
 
 South Italian 
 
 Scotch 
 
 English 
 
 White of native father. 
 Welsh 
 
 Russian 
 
 Scotch 
 
 North Italian 
 
 Irish 
 
 Irish 
 
 Welsh 
 
 Pennsylvania: 
 Slovenian 
 
 Slovak 
 
 White of native father. 
 
 Pennsylvania: 
 Lithuanian . . 
 
 
 Russian 
 
 White of native father. 
 South: 
 Slovak 
 
 White of native father . 
 South: 
 Slovak 
 
 Polish 
 
 White of native father. 
 Southwest: 
 Lithuanian 
 
 
 White of native father. 
 
 Southwest: 
 
 Slovenian 
 
 South Italian 
 
 German 
 
 White of native father. 
 
 White of native father. 
 
 Comparable data on the earnings of employees engaged 
 in the same class of work are available only for West 
 Virginia. The average earnings of pick-miners for one 
 month were as follows: American, white, $78.18; Magyar 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, Tables 34-35, pp. 
 54-56. 
 
The Coal Miners 443 
 
 and Slovak, $76.68; South Italian, $69.11.* There is no 
 substantial difference between the Magyar and Slovaks, on 
 the one hand, and the white Americans, on the other; their 
 wages averaged about $3.00 a day. The earnings of the 
 Italians were lower, but this may have been due to 
 the fact that some of them did not work every day in the 
 month. 2 
 
 The conclusion of the Commission with regard to the^ 
 Virginia and West Virginia coal fields is that "although it 
 is not clear that the employment of the immigrant has 
 reduced wages . . . it is obvious that if immigrant labor 
 had not been available either a much higher wage would 
 have been paid, more labor-saving devices used, or less 
 development would have been possible. " 3 In other words, 
 wages have not been reduced, but had there been no immi- 
 grants on hand, either wages would have been higher, 
 or they would not have been higher. The conclusion is 
 indisputable. 
 
 The Immigration Commission holds the recent immi- 
 grants responsible for the evils of the company houses and 
 the company stores. It is the usual method of reasoning: 
 the company house and the company store exist only 
 V because the recent immigrants "consent" to accept them. 4 
 This is a consistent application of the theory of "freedom of 
 contract": wages are low, because wage-earners "consent" 
 to accept low wages; hours of labor are long, because 
 laborers "consent" to work long hours; factories are un- 
 sanitary, because operatives "consent" to work in unsani- 
 tary factories. Every problem involved in the relation 
 between labor and capital finds an easy solution in this 
 philosophy. 
 
 The fact is that the real estate and the mercantile end of 
 a mining company's business are often no less important, 
 as sources of income, than the mine. There are mining 
 companies whose sales of coal do not cover their operating 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 202. 2 Ibid. 
 
 3 Ibid., p. 223. Ibid., pp. 659, 666. 
 
444 Immigration and Labor 
 
 expenses, but the renting of houses to employees and the 
 profits of the commissary store yield enough to pay divi- 
 dends on the entire investment. This system is much older 
 than immigration from Southern and Eastern Europe. 
 
 An item in the Pottsville Miners' Journal for January, 1850, states 
 that there were 42,000 houses rented by the operators in the anthracite 
 coal fields. From the earliest records of mining, operators have erected 
 abodes for their employees, and the practice has been continued until 
 very recent times among all the companies. 1 
 
 Company houses are as usual in the South, where the 
 white miners are mostly of old American stock, as in those 
 fields where recent immigrants predominate. 
 
 The company store has also had a long history. 
 
 The Pottsville Miners' Journal states that in 1848 . . . men worked 
 for $3.50 a week and took that out in orders. ... In 1850, the laborer 
 got from 60 cents to 65 cents a day and the miner from 80 cents to 90 
 cents. These were low wages but they were actually lower than the 
 amounts specified, for the men were not paid in money. They had to 
 take their earnings out in goods which made a difference of from 15 to 
 20 per cent against the wage-earner. 3 
 
 Many and persistent attempts have been made to do away with this 
 evil, all of which so far have come short of their object. It was an 
 issue of the Bates strike of 1849. The Workingmen's Benevolent 
 Association of 1868-75 attempted to remove it. It was one of the 
 planks in the platform of the Knights of Labor who flourished in the 
 Middle and Southern coal fields in 1886-88. And the labor organiza- 
 tion which now flourishes in the anthracite coal fields has undertaken to 
 correct this evil. "'What the employees could not do by labor unions 
 representatives have tried to do by legislative enactment. In 
 June, 1 88 1, a law was passed to enforce payment in lawful money of 
 the United States or "any order or other paper whatsoever, redeemable 
 for its face value in lawful money of the United States." This law 
 was declared unconstitutional. ... In June, 1891, another act was 
 passed, making it unlawful for "any mining or manufacturing corpora- 
 tion of the commonwealth, or the officers or stockholders of any such 
 corporation, to engage in or carry on any store known as company 
 store." . . . Another attempt was made at the recommendation of 
 an investigating committee in 1897 to abolish this evil. All these 
 
 1 Peter Roberts: The Anthracite Coaljndustry, p. 130. 
 Ibid., p. 109. 
 
The Coal Miners 445 
 
 legislative actaJhayfi mme shortj^ their objects. The company store 
 still flourishes. . . . Their number is not as large as they once were; 
 they are gradually dying out, but the institution dies hard. 1 
 
 In West Virginia "every mining company has a company 
 store, and the operatives are compelled to deal in the 
 company store, because they are paid only once a month, 
 but may between pay-days obtain trading scrip which is 
 good only at the company stores." 2 Nearly one half (46 
 per cent) of all mine workers in West Virginia are native y 
 white Americans, and only 30 per cent are immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. 3 It is clear that the recent^f 
 immigrant is no more responsible for the company store 
 than the native American miner. 
 
 It is a fair conclusion from all available facts that the 
 terms of employment in the coal mines at present are in no 
 respect less favorable to the mine Worker, and that the 
 wages are higher, than in the past, when the bulk of the 
 mine workers were native Americans or immigrants from 
 Northern and Western Europe. 
 
 The ability of the wage-earner to influence the terms of ^ 
 employment in large-scale industry finds full expression I 
 only in collective bargaining. The history of labor unions / 
 in the bituminous coal-mining industry, according to the 
 Immigration Commission's version, has been a constant 
 struggle on the part of the English-speaking mine workers 
 to organize the Southern and Eastern Europeans and to 
 hold them in line. 
 
 ( 
 
 In the Pennsylvania bituminous mining area the entire period from , 
 1870 to 1894 was marked by a series of labor dissensions and strikes, 
 each of which left the labor organizations in a weaker condition than did 
 its predecessor, for the reason that the older employees, who were the 
 leaders in the movement for higher wages and better working conditions, 
 finding themselves unable to control the conditions imposed by the 
 increasing employment of recent immigrants, and finally realizing that it 
 
 1 Peter Roberts : The Anthracite Coal Industry, pp. 129-130. 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, p. 201. 
 3 Ibid., p. 161. 
 
446 Immigration and Labor 
 
 was impossible to control the incoming supply of immigrant labor, 
 abandoned the Pennsylvania mines and sought similar employment in 
 other bituminous localities where the pressure of competition of recent 
 immigrants was not so strong. . . . Practically, the same situation 
 with the same results was experienced in the mines of West Virginia. 
 Recent immigrants did not enter the mines of that State in large num- 
 bers . . . until after the year 1890. The competition was soon felt, 
 however, and the significance of their presence revealed by the strikes 
 which occurred in the Fairmont, Elk Garden, and other fields in the 
 years 1894 and 1895. Natives and older immigrant employees left 
 the mines, as they had done in Pennsylvania, thus creating vacancies 
 which were filled by the employment of additional numbers of recent 
 immigrants, who reduced the strength of the labor organizations. The 
 * rapid expansion of the mining operations after 1894 also brought into 
 the mining fields a constantly growing number of Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans, who completely inundated the older employees and uncon- 
 sciously, but_effectually, Demoralized the labor unions and put aTstop to 
 anyeffbrts toward organization. . . . |In the Middle West] during the 
 past ten years . . . although the labor unions have largely maintained 
 their strength, conditions have changed and the preservation of the 
 standards of the organization has been a matter of the greatest difficulty. 
 Mining operations have undergone a great expansion, and recourse has 
 been had to races of recent immigration in greater and greater numbers. 
 These newcomers have entered the labor organizations principally 
 because they have considered it a necessary step preliminary to securing 
 
 <work in the mines, and not because they have had any sympathy or 
 interest in the labor-union program. They have also manifested com- 
 paratively little activity in its behalf. l 
 
 The preceding summary abounds in errors of fact] which 
 produce a distorted view of the history oFTrade-unionism in 
 the bituminous coal-mining industry. The cardinal fact 
 of that history is that so long as the English-speaking 
 mine workers were in the majority, their organizations were 
 ephemeral and their strikes mostly unsuccessful; it is only 
 since the Southern and Eastern Europeans 'have become an 
 important factor in the coal mines that the miners* organi- 
 zation has gained strength. The growth of the United 
 Mine Workers of America appears from Table 130 next 
 following. Whereas in 1890 scarcely 15 per cent of all 
 mine workers in the United States were affiliated with 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I , p. 535. 
 
The Coal Miners 447 
 
 labor unions, in 1904 the proportion of organized mine 
 workers exceeded one half of the total number employed. x 
 Since 1898 terms of employment in the bituminous coal 
 mines are periodically agreed upon between conferees of the 
 conventions of organized mine operators and organized 
 mine workers, holding sessions after the fashion of two 
 houses of an industrial parliament. 
 
 TABLE 130. 
 
 MEMBERSHIP OF THE UNITED MINE WORKERS OF AMERICA, 1890-1904. a 
 
 Year Number Year Number 
 
 1890 20,912 1898 32,9O2 
 
 1891 17,044 1899 61,887 
 
 1892. I9.376 1900 115,521 
 
 1893 14,244 1901 198,024 
 
 1894 , 17,628 1902 175,367 
 
 1895 10,871 1903 247,240 
 
 1896 9,617 1904 : 260,075 
 
 1897.. 9,731 
 
 The Industrial Commission says in a survey of the history 
 f the miners' unions up to the end of the past century: 
 
 Labor organization among the coal miners has passed through ex- 
 traordinary vicissitudes. The Welsh, Scotch, English, and Irish miners 
 were well organized and maintained high wages, but in 1875, not owing 
 to the presence of immigrants, but as a result of a strike against a 
 falling market, their organization was entirely broken and their wages 
 greatly reduced. Not until 1897, in the bituminous field, and 1900, 
 in the anthracite field, was a reorganization effected, this time not of 
 the original British stock alone, but also of the mixed nationalities from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe. . . . While there have been serious 
 problems in the organization of mixed nationalities, an equally serious 
 problem which has confronted the organization of these immigrants 
 has been the competition of the unorganized Americans of native stock. Y 
 This was fully shown in the experience of the miners prior to 1897, 
 when their organizations in Northern Illinois were defeated by the 
 native Americans in Southern Illinois. In the first mining district of 
 Illinois the per cent of Americans is only eleven, and in the seventh, in 
 the Southern part of the State, it is eighty. Yet, it was these American 
 miners in the thick and more easily mined veins of the Southern section 
 
 1 Frank Julian Warne: The Coal Mine Workers, pp. 120, 206, 212, 218. 
 'Ibid., pp. 117, 120, 212, 218. 
 
448 Immigration and Labor 
 
 whose competition reduced wages so low that they were actually earning 
 less than in the Northern districts. The success of the strike in 1897 
 consisted mainly in the fact that the Southern American-born miners 
 were brought into the Union and placed on a basis of equal competition 
 with the foreign-born miners. A similar condition at the present time 
 confronts the mining organization of the four great States of the bitumi- 
 nous field in the competition of West Virginia, where the native whites 
 of native parents number 57 H per cent and the colored miners number 
 21 per cent of the total number of miners, compared with 20 to 48 per 
 cent native whites of both native and foreign parentage in the other 
 States. Prices and wages in West Virginia are 30 to 70 per cent below 
 those under similar conditions in the other States. . . . The organiza- 
 tion of 150,000 bituminous mine workers, over one half of whom are 
 foreign-born of diverse races, is menaced more by the unorganized 
 Americans of native stock than by their own internal divisions. 1 
 
 In another part of the same report the history of the 
 contests in Illinois is given in greater detail : 
 
 The jeopardy fl-d jWgat_nfJjhe tinionsJias-beea- owing as often to 
 thecompetition of unorganized A.mencass^^_na,tive stock in new 
 fiekJsTas in the competition of the foreign-born. This is fully demon- 
 stratecTBy the experience of the miners prior to 1897, when they were 
 defeated by the competition of Southern Illinois, and, since 1897, when 
 they were jeopardized by the competition of West Virginia. Beginning 
 with 1886 . . . the local organization of miners known as the Federa- 
 tion of Miners and Mine Laborers acquired such strength that it was 
 able to summon the operators of Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Illinois to 
 annual conferences for the purposes of agreements regarding the scale 
 of wages in these competitive States. . . . During the entire period 
 of these interstate conferences, from 1886 to 1893, it has been impossible 
 for the unions to organize Southern Illinois. The miners injthat section 
 w^re predominatingly Arrlencans^ Theyj^re^larm laborers who had 
 timlext5D4J3e-nitn^r^ a source of readylSshTTTTTheir rates per ton 
 for mining coal were twenty-eight to thirty-eight cents, as compared 
 with sixty-two to seventy cents in the Northern fields. ... In order 
 to protect the miners in the Northern, thin-veined districts, and permit 
 their coal to come into the market at living wages, the union has forced 
 the miners in the Southern, thick-veined districts to increase their 
 earnings from the lowest in the State to the highest in the State. This 
 is one of the necessities of the system of differentials in arranging scales 
 of prices for different sections of the^same competitive field, and it was 
 exactly the evil of the former unorganized condition that the American 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. xxxv.-xxxvi. 
 
The Coal Miners 449 
 
 miners in the Southern field had reduced their compensation so low 
 notwithstanding the greater productivity of the mines, that they were 
 earning less than the meager wages of the foreign-born miners in the 
 Northern fields. . . . The present high wages of the Southern field are not,\ 
 therefore, owing to a higher standard of living or superior capacity for 
 organization of Americans as compared with foreigners, but are owing to C 
 the inj^ajj^iandj/nterference oj fp feigners, who, in self-protection, forced 1 
 the Americans to a higher position than the one they were willing to accept.* 
 
 The Immigration Commission quotes the opinion of 
 "the older employees" "that in general the immigration 
 of Southern and Eastern Europeans has been very disastrous 
 to the labor unions in the coal-mining industry. In some 
 districts the unions have been entirely disrupted, and old X 
 operatives assert that this was directly due to the coming 
 of the later immigrants." 2 The illustrations cited by the 
 Commission in support of this claim prove the very op- 
 posite of it. In the strike of 1884 in the Connelsville coke 
 region the Slav, Magyar, and Italian workmen joined the I 
 American and Irish strikers. The strike was defeated, ' 
 but "the percentage of recent immigrants was relatively 
 small" ; no reason is given why the defeat should be attrib- 
 uted to that small number rather than to the weakness of 
 the English-speaking majority. In 1 890 the strike was again 
 defeated, although "in this case also the immigrants joined 
 the strike." In 1894 the men struck again. ' The Ameri- 
 cans, English, and Irish were leaders of the strike and the 
 immigrants very generally joined the organization which 
 had been effected only two weeks previously." The strike 
 originally extended to seventy-seven out of eighty-five 
 plants; after six weeks of striking ninety- two per cent of 
 all ovens were idle. By that time, however, many of the 
 strikers "were enduring severe hardships." Still the 
 majority held out for two months longer, and a minority 
 stayed out in all for five months. The strike was defeated. 
 That was the end of the organization in that field. 3 
 
 1 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. 407-409. 
 3 Reports of the Immigration Commission^ vol. 6, p. 332. 
 3 Ibid., pp. 332-334. 
 
450 Immigration and Labor 
 
 It is sought to fasten the responsibility for the defeat of 
 these strikes upon the Slav, Magyar, and Italian strikers; 
 "the American and Irish leaders" are said to have "found 
 difficulty in restraining them from violence during the 
 strikes." In general, it is remarked that "in strikes the 
 recent immigrant members . . . are often inclined to 
 resort to violence and other methods that bring the union 
 and its_c^^eJnto-xiisrpute7 Tr ~ 
 
 In view of the recent developments in the McNamara case 
 these protestations of "the American and Irish leaders" 
 may be accepted cum grano salis. " The undesirable alien " 
 is a convenient scapegoat to appease public_ppinion 1 _ which 
 is not burdened with memories of the long ago. The ter- 
 rorism of the Molly Maguires has a literature. Rioting is 
 chronicled as an incident of almost every strike of import- 
 ance in the coal mines for the last sixty years. The first 
 great strike of which there is any record occurred in the 
 spring of 1849 under the leadership of the Bates union. 
 
 "The strike was accompanied by violence. Miners, 
 armed with cudgels, formed themselves into bands and 
 marched down the Black Valley to collieries which were 
 working, and by intimidation compelled the men to join 
 their ranks." 
 
 In the strike of 1868 an effort was made by the strikers 
 to draw into the contest all mine workers of the anthracite 
 region. 
 
 They marched to the Mahanoy Valley and stopped the collieries 
 there, then they advanced to the Schuylkill Valley and did the same 
 there. Thus most of the Southern and Middle collieries were closed. 
 They resolved then to continue their march to the Wyoming Valley 
 and persuade the miners there to join their ranks. The employees of 
 the Wilkes-Barre District joined them. Along the line of march they 
 compelled all classes of workmen to throw down their tools and fall 
 into line. The mechanics of Wilkes-Barre were forced to quit work 
 and join the strikers; the same was done with the force working on the 
 Wilkes-Barre jail at the time. The sheriff of Luzerne County addressed 
 them and asked them to disperse, but to no purpose. 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, pp. 332-333. 
 
The Coal Miners 451 
 
 On January 10, 1871, the Workingmen's Benevolent 
 Association declared a general strike in all anthracite col- 
 lieries in sympathy with the miners of the Northern field. 
 Practically all collieries were shut down and remained so 
 until May, when " a few shafts were started by the 
 Delaware, Lackawanna & Western Company. Riots en- 
 sued. The military power of the State was called out and 
 in a conflicit between it and the strikers, two of the miners 
 were shot and several wounded. ... Labor was utterly 
 defeated in the contest." 
 
 In 1877 the great railroad strike tied up the anthracite 
 coal mines. The miners of the Delaware, Lackawanna & 
 Western and of the Delaware & Hudson collieries joined 
 in the strike. " Labor riots were the order of the day." 1 
 
 This is the record of the anthracite region only. The 
 battle of the Homestead strikers with the Pinkertons in 
 1892, the troubles in the metalliferous mines of Colorado and 
 Idaho, the recent strike of the firemen on the Southern rail- 
 ways, and many other episodes in which none but English- 
 speaking workmen were involved, conclusively prove that 
 violence jn_ strikes is not a racial characteristic of "the\/ 
 recent_immigrants from Southern and Eastern Europe." A 
 
 Since the United Mine Workers has won the support of 
 these immigrants, who now form the backbone of that 
 organization, very little is heard of strike riots. For the 
 past fourteen years, as stated, terms of employment in the 
 bituminous mines are peaceably agreed upon between 
 representatives of organized mine operators and organized 
 mine workers. 
 
 The United Mine Workers has so far failed in its 
 efforts to gain a foothold in West Virginia and in the South- 
 ern fields. But its defeat is not attributable to recent 
 immigrants. "Until 1897 the immigrant labor employed 
 was not in excess of 10 per cent of the total operating 
 forces." 3 Consequently, the defeat of the strikes of 1894 
 
 1 Roberts, loc. cit., pp. 172-181. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, pp. 146-147. 
 
452 Immigration and Labor 
 
 and 1895 could not have been brought on by recent immi- 
 grants. The next strike took place in 1902. " A majority 
 of the mines were closed for a considerable period." The 
 operators imported strike-breakers Americans, as well as 
 immigrants and the strike ultimately failed. 1 
 
 Since that time West Virginia has been a non-union field. 
 But it had been a non-union field also previous to the strike 
 of 1902, when 57.8 per cent of all mine workers were native 
 white of native parentage and 73.4 per cent belonged to the 
 English-speaking races. Yet shortly before the strike of 
 1902, prices and wages in West Virginia were "30 to 
 70 per cent below those under similar conditions in the 
 other States." 2 
 
 On the other hand, in Alabama only 13 per cent 
 of all mine workers are foreign-born, and only 10 per 
 cent from Southern and Eastern Europe, while 26 per 
 cent are native white of native parentage and 31 per cent 
 English-speaking white, the other 59 per cent being 
 negroes. Yet "a very small proportion of natives . . . 
 are identified with organized labor . . . for the rea- 
 son that in only one small district of the Southern field 
 is organized labor recognized." 3 A series of questions 
 naturally arises : Why is organized labor not recognized in 
 the Southern field? Why have the natives not organized? 
 Why have they not won recognition for organized labor? 
 There seems to be no chosen people endowed with special 
 trade-union qualifications: there are well-organized mines 
 with a predominantly non-English-speaking force and unor- 
 ganized mines manned chiefly by Anglo-Saxons. 
 
 The inability of the immigrants to understand the English 
 language may have been an obstacle to organization among 
 them in the early days when they were few. At present, 
 however, when every European language is spoken in 
 every mining field, there is no difficulty in rinding a 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, pp. 150-151. 
 3 Reports of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv., pp. 407-408. 
 s Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 7, pp. 142, 196. 
 
The Coal Miners 453 
 
 sufficient number of English-speaking persons of each 
 nationality who can represent their countrymen in union 
 matters. x 
 
 There are no available statistics of the distribution of 
 union membership by nationality. It can be estimated, 
 however, for the State of Illinois. In 1904, 51,167 out of 
 54,685 mine workers in that State, i. e. t 93 per cent were 
 affiliated with the United Mine Workers of America. 2 
 According to the census of 1900, 78 per cent of the total 
 number of mine workers in Illinois were of "English-speak- 
 ing" parentage. 3 Assuming that every one of the latter 
 class was a member of the organization 1 5 per cent of the 
 remaining 22 per cent, i.e., 75 per cent of all persons of Slav 
 and Italian parentage, must likewise have been affiliated 
 with the organization. In fact, the percentage of organized 
 Slavs and Italians must have been higher, since their pro- 
 portion among the coal miners of Illinois had increased from 
 1900 to 1904. Moreover, it is reasonable to assume that 
 some of the English-speaking mine workers did not belong 
 to the union, which would further add to the estimated per- 
 centage of organized Slavs and Italians. On the other 
 hand, in Kentucky 99.5 per cent of all mine workers were of 
 English-speaking parentage, and in Tennessee 99 per cent. 4 
 But the proportion of union men among them was 2 1 per 
 cent in Kentucky and 24 per cent in Tennessee. 5 
 
 The most significant test of the strength of the organiza- 
 tion is its recognition by the Steel Trust : 
 
 The Slav in the mines is paid from 50 to 90 per cent more per 
 hour than his countrymen working in the mills and factories of Pitts- 
 burg, at jobs requiring the same amount of skill and strength. In 
 many cases the same company is compelled to pay these different rates 
 for the same class of labor. The great steel mills and glass factories 
 
 1 The proportion of English-speaking persons among the Southern 
 and Eastern European coal miners enumerated by the Immigration Com- 
 mission varied for different nationalities from 30 to 75 per cent. 
 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 196, Table 122. 
 
 3 Wame, loc. cit., p. 1 1 7. See Appendix, Table XXVII. 
 
 < Ibid. sWarne, 
 
454 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the district are all non-union. The companies which own them also 
 own many of the coal mines of Allegheny and Washington counties. 
 These are all union mines, and the United States Steel Corporation, 
 Jones & Laughlin, the Pittsburgh Glass Company, as mine owners, sign 
 agreements with the unions which provide for an eight-hour day and 
 a scale of wages almost double what they pay for the same labor in the 
 manufacturing plants. Prof. John R. Commons has summed up, for 
 the Pittsburgh Survey, a comparison of the men in the mills with those 
 in the mines, in the following words: 
 
 "Taking everything into account wages, hours, leisure, cost of 
 living, conditions of work I should say that the common laborer 
 employed by the steel companies in their mines is 50 to 90 per 
 cent better off than the same grade of labor employed at their mills 
 and furnaces; that the semi-skilled labor employed at piece rates is 
 40 to 50 per cent better off; but among the highest paid labor, the 
 steel roller and the mine worker are about the same."* 
 
 It should be borne in mind that the highest-paid positions, 
 both in the mines and in the mills, are controlled exclusively 
 by native Americans or by the old immigrant races, whereas 
 the unskilled positions are practically all held by Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans. In the semi-skilled positions, the 
 English-speaking and the non-English-speaking workmen 
 meet on common ground. It thus appears that the activity 
 of jthe union has secured the best terms for the Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans, and a very substantial improvement for 
 alTempIoyees where__the_ Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 arejajactor in the labor situations, whereas in the highest 
 grades controlled by the English-speaking races, the organ- 
 ized mine-workers have gained no better terms than those 
 which the steel companies were willing to offer to the 
 unorganized steel workers. 
 
 It is worthy of note that the Immigration Commission, 
 while dwelling upon the failure of the United Mine Workers 
 to extend its control to the bituminous fields of Pennsyl- 
 vania outside of the Pittsburgh district, has passed in silence 
 the signal success of the same organization in the anthracite 
 coal fields, where the same nationalities are employed as in 
 the bituminous mines of Pennsylvania. 
 
 1 Leiserson, loc. cit., pp. 318-319. 
 
The Coal Miners 455 
 
 The history of organization in the anthracite coal field 
 begins as early as 1848. In that year the "Bates Union," 
 so-called, was organized. It existed only two years. There 
 was no organization in the anthracite coal fields until 
 1868, when the Workingmen's Benevolent Association was 
 founded. It succeeded in organizing for a while 85 
 per cent of all mine workers. But in 1871, after an unsuc- 
 cessful strike, it lost the Northern field, which remained 
 unorganized for twenty-six years. In the Middle and 
 Southern fields it led a moribund existence until 1875. For 
 nine years there was again no organization. From 1884 
 to 1888 there were first two organizations which in 1887 
 consolidated into one under the auspices of the Knights of 
 Labor, which was at that time in the heyday of its triumphs. 
 But a disastrous strike which lasted from November, 
 1887, to March, 1888, put an end to the organization of the 
 anthracite coal miners. 
 
 In 1897 the United Mine Workers undertook the organi- 
 zation of the anthracite mines. Its growth was slow until 
 1900, when it engaged in its first great strike which was won 
 after all collieries had been practically tied up for six weeks. x 
 The strike of 1900 was followed by the great struggle of 
 1902 which was ended by the award of President Roosevelt's 
 Anthracite Coal Strike Commission. 
 
 , This brief survey shows that all organizations of the 
 English-speaking workers were short-lived and seldom sur- 
 vivect~c>ne unsuccessful strike. It is only since the~a3vent~ 
 of the Southern and Eastern Europeans that the union has 
 taken a firm hold of the industry. 
 
 Dr. Roberts, reviewing the history of unionism in the 
 anthracite coal industry, says : 
 
 John Graham Brooks, when he studied the Lattimer riots of 1897, 
 found on the Hazleton Mountain over a dozen nationalities. He ex- 
 pressed the conviction that it was a hopeless task to attempt to form 
 them into a labor organization. Paul de Rousiers, in his essay on 
 Les Tentatives de Monopolisation de I' Anthracite, expressed a similar 
 
 1 Roberts, loc. cit., p. 184. 
 
456 Immigration and Labor 
 
 opinion. He compared the present personnel of anthracite employees, 
 "largely composed of Polanders, Hungarians, and Lithuanians, who are 
 turbulent and incapable of being advantageously formed into an 
 association," with the Americans, Germans, and English of 1868, who 
 so successfully organized the Workingmen's Benevolent Association, 
 and believed they could not be successfully organized into a labor 
 organization. Both eminent men have proved to be false prophets. 
 Thestanchest members of the union are the Slavs, and the organizers of 
 the~United Mine Workers of America have successfully overcome racial 
 differences, national antipathies and industrial prejudices, and formed 
 into one body the fifteen or sixteen nationalities now constituting the 
 anthracite mining communities. 1 
 
 The opinions of those "false prophets" were still reit- 
 erated after the strikes of 1900 and 1902 by labor men, who 
 "had learned nothing and forgotten nothing," and were 
 embodied by the Immigration Commission in its report. 
 
 These foreigners, [says Dr. Roberts elsewhere] have proved capable 
 of forming labor organizations which are more compact and united 
 than any which ever existed among the various English-speaking 
 nationalities, who first constituted these communities. It is conceded 
 by men intimate with the situation throughout the coal fields during 
 the last strike, that its universality was more due to the Slav than to 
 any other nationality. There would have been in all probability a 
 break in the ranks in Schuylkill County had it not been for the firm and 
 uncompromising stand of the Slavs in favor of the strike. They have 
 been trained to obedience, and when they organize they move with a 
 unanimity that is very seldom seen among nations who pride themselves 
 on personal liberty and free discussion. 3 
 
 These lines were written by Dr. Roberts previous to the 
 strike of 1902. The significance of the latter was that the 
 other side to the controversy was a trust which was (and is) 
 in complete control of the whole anthracite coal industry. 
 The outcome of the contest has been the creation of a demo- 
 cratic organization of all mine workers to which the trust 
 cannot deny recognition, with a machinery for fixing wages 
 and other terms of employment, as well as for the settlement 
 of disputes. 
 
 After twenty years of immigration from Southern and 
 
 1 Roberts, loc. ciL, pp. 196-197. Ibid., pp. 171-172. 
 
The Coal Miners 457 
 
 Eastern Europe, the coal miners are more strongly organized 
 than they had ever been before the English-speaking mine 
 workers relinquished the lower grades of work to the recent 
 immigrants; the hours of labor have been reduced, wages 
 have risen, and the majority of the older employees have 
 advanced on the scale of occupations. 
 
 On the other hand, a "small part [of the 'pioneer em- 
 ployees and their descendants'] consisting of the inert, 
 unambitious, thriftless element, have remained on the lower 
 level of the scale of occupations where they are in open com- 
 petition with the majority of the races of recent immigra- 
 tion in comparison with whom they are generally considered 
 less efficient." 1 It is said in their behalf that their anxiety 
 to be "removed from contact and competition with the 
 immigrant" has "forced" them "into day or shift work^at 
 a lower rate of pay than in digging coal." 2 In order to 
 escape the ruinous competition of the recent immigrant, 
 the English-speaking miner, it would seem, is willing to 
 accept lower wages than the immigrant. It may be ques- 
 tioned whether this small residue of English-speaking mine 
 workers who are "considered less efficient" than the South- 
 ern and Eastern Europeans could have succeeded better in 
 competition with native or English-speaking miners, had 
 there been no immigration from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe. Probably the reference to "competition with the 
 immigrant" is merely a pleonasm, the idea being that the 
 English-speaking miner is willing to make a financial sacrifice 
 in order to be "removed from contact with the immigrant." 
 The objection to the recent immigrant is accordingly in- 
 spired by pure and simple race prejudice. This is, how- 
 ever, beside the question, so long as it is maintained that 
 immigration should be treated "upon economic or business 
 considerations. ' ' 3 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, pp. 536-537. 
 
 2 Ibid., vol. 6, pp. 666-667; vol. 7, p. 222. 
 
 3 Recommendations of the Immigration Commission. 
 
CHAPTER XXII 
 
 WORK ACCIDENTS 
 
 greatest of all the dangers of the new immigration, 
 which have been discovered by the investigation of the 
 Immigration Commission, is that their employment in 
 mines and manufactures jeopardizes the lives of American 
 wage-earners. The Commission has devoted to the sub- 
 ject a special chapter in its report on bituminous coal 
 mines. 1 Its conclusions are summarized by Professors 
 Jenks and Lauck as follows 2 : 
 
 The lack of industrial training and experience of the recent im- 
 migrant before coming to the United States, together with his illit- 
 eracy and inability to speak English, has had the effect of exposing the 
 original employees to unsafe and unsanitary working conditions, or has 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, chapter viii., pp. 
 209-241; also, pp. 491-492, 543, 651-652; vol. 7, pp. 68-69. 
 
 a The Commission is, of course, not responsible officially for the 
 statement of those authors. But the book is very largely a verbatim 
 transcript of the most essential portions of the Commission's voluminous 
 report. On the subject of accidents, the report of the Commission says 
 in Volume 6: 
 
 "The responsibility for accidents rests in most cases with the men 
 injured . . . they know little or nothing of rock formations, of fire 
 damp, of the properties of coal dust, and of the handling of explosives 
 matters about which every coal miner should be thoroughly informed. 
 To determine whether a piece of slate or -roof is or is not likely to fall 
 often requires a considerable degree of experience, and the majority 
 of the Slavs, Magyars, and Italians have not this experience. Another 
 element of danger is contributed by the fact that few of the recent 
 immigrants speak or understand English, while almost none are able 
 to read or write the language. It is probable that the instructions of 
 the mine bosses and inspectors are, because of this fact, frequently 
 
 458 
 
Work Accidents 459 
 
 led to the imposition of conditions of employment which the native 
 American or older immigrant employees have considered unsatisfactory 
 and in some cases unbearable. When the older employees have found 
 dangerous and unhealthy conditions prevailing in the mines and manu- 
 facturing establishments and have protested, the recent immigrant employees^ 
 usually through ignorance of mining or other working methods, have 
 manifested a willingness to accept the alleged unsatisfactory conditions. 
 In a large number of cases, the lack of training and experience of the 
 Southern and Eastern European affects only his own safety. On the 
 other hand, his ignorant acquiescence in dangerous and unsanitary work- 
 ing conditions may make the continuance of such conditions possible and 
 become a menace to a part or to the whole of an operating force of an 
 industrial establishment. In mining, the presence of an untrained 
 employee may constitute an element of danger to the entire body of 
 workmen. There seems to be a direct causal relation between the 
 extensive employment of recent immigrants in American mines and the 
 extraordinary increase within recent years in the number of mining 
 accidents. // is an undisputed fact that the greatest number of accidents 
 in bituminous coal mines arise from two causes: (i) the recklessness, and 
 (2) the ignorance and inexperience, of employees. When the lack of 
 training of the recent immigrant abroad is considered in connection 
 with the fact that he becomes a workman in the mines immediately 
 upon his arrival in this country, and when it is recalled that a large 
 proportion of the new arrivals are not only illiterate and unable to read 
 any precautionary notices posted in the mines, but also unable to speak 
 English and consequently without ability to comprehend instructions 
 intelligently, the inference is plain that the employment of recent immi- 
 
 niisunderstood. An inspector, for example, tells an immigrant miner, 
 in English of course, that his roof needs propping. The miner seems 
 to understand, but does not, and a fall results. In some mines printed 
 signs are used to indicate the presence of gas or other peril. These are 
 quite unintelligible to most of the foreigners, because, through lack of 
 training, they are unable to recognize the presence of danger, and further, 
 because of their keenness for earning money, the immigrants are often 
 willing to work in places where more experienced or more intelligent 
 men would refuse to work. For the same reasons they will frequently 
 be satisfied with and accept mine equipment too defective for safety. 
 . . . The ignorance and inexperience of the workmen of the races of 
 recent immigration employed in mines are responsible in a large measure 
 for the high death rate reported. Owing to the large number of factors 
 affecting the situation, no hard and fast conclusion can be drawn, but 
 the inference from the data available clearly warrants the assertion 
 that the employment of immigrant mine workers has a direct bearing 
 upon mining casualties." (pp. 232-233, 241.) 
 
460 Immigration and Labor 
 
 grants has caused a deterioration in working conditions. No complete 
 statistics have been compiled as to the connection between accidents 
 and races employed, but the figures available clearly indicate the con- 
 clusion that there has been a direct relation between the employment 
 of untrained foreigners and the prevalence of mining casualties. 1 
 
 The two causes from which, according to this explanation, 
 the greatest number of accidents arise, are but the familiar 
 defenses in an employer's liability case under the common 
 law: (i) negligence of the injured employee or of a fellow- 
 servant, (2) assumption of risk by the injured employee. 
 
 The Immigration Commission rests its conclusions on 
 the opinions of State mining officials and experts of the 
 Federal Government, seemingly supported by an array of 
 statistical figures. An examination of these authorities, 
 however, will show that they have merely accepted the 
 mine operator's point of view without turning their atten- 
 tion to the technical and the economic side of coal mining 
 in the United States. 
 
 Miss Eastman, in her study of work accidents for the 
 Pittsburgh Survey, has carefully scrutinized the sources of 
 the accepted explanation of the causes of work accidents. 
 In vivid conversational style she thus characterizes the 
 typical attitude "of those best informed upon the subject" 3 : 
 
 "So you have come to Pittsburgh to study accidents, have you?" 
 says the superintendent, or the claim agent, or the general manager, as 
 the case may be. "Well, I 've been in this business fifteen years and 
 I can tell you one thing right now, p5 per cent of our accidents 
 are due to the carelessness of the man who gets hurt. Why, you simply 
 would n't believe the things they '11 do. For instance, I remember a 
 man," and he goes on to relate the most telling incident he knows to 
 prove his assertion. This is the almost invariable reaction of the 
 Pittsburgh employer and his representatives to a query about industrial 
 accidents. And the statements of such men are the chief source of 
 effective public opinion on the subject in Pittsburgh.* 
 
 1 Jenks and Lauck, loc. cit., pp. 189-190. 
 
 * Phrase used by the Immigration Commission (Reports, vol. 6, p. 
 216). 
 
 3 Crystal Eastman: Work-Accidents and the Law, p. 84. 
 
Work Accidents 461 
 
 The returns of the mine inspectors on the causes of acci- 
 dents are based upon the results of the coroners' inquests. 
 Miss Eastman questions the reliability of the evidence 
 secured at the inquests : 
 
 Foremen and fire bosses are required at once to inspect a room where 
 an accident has occurred, and, if death results, one of them is always 
 summoned to the inquest. He almost invariably testifies, "I found 
 plenty of posts in the room." Since it is his business by law to see 
 that there are plenty of posts in the room, and since the inquest is very 
 casual, unimpressive, he could hardly be expected to testify otherwise. 
 Private conversation with miners sometimes brings other information 
 to light. ... An old Scotch miner of sixty, said . . . that he "had 
 often seen the foreman and boss hurry to a room where an accident had 
 happened and fill it with posts, so that when the inspector arrived there 
 would be plenty of posts on hand." 1 The coroners' records were, as a 
 rule, meager, sometimes illegible, and almost never clear and satisfactory 
 in detail. The testimony, moreover, has a tendency to lean to one 
 side. The witnesses are employees of the company, including almost 
 always the superior of the man killed. It is to his interest to clear him- 
 self of all implications; second, to clear his employer. The easiest and 
 safest way of accomplishing these ends is to blame the dead man.* 
 
 Thus, when we read in the reports of the Pennsylvania 
 Department of Mines for 1907 that "a careful examination 
 of the reports shows that 332 accidents, or 41.19 per cent, 
 were due to the carelessness of the victim," 3 this statement 
 means no more than that the reports which reached the 
 department "blamed the dead man" in two cases out of 
 every five. Of course, 41.19 per cent is still short of a 
 majority, but it is turned into a majority of 62.29 per cent 
 by omitting "the 273 fatalities of the Naomi and Darr 
 mines, which were caused by the carelessness of other 
 persons. ' ' 4 These undefined ' ' other persons ' ' include ' ' offi- 
 cials in direct charge of the mines." The propriety of 
 omitting two great mine disasters, which resulted in the 
 
 1 Crystal Eastman: Work- Accidents and the Law, p. 39. 
 a Ibid., p. 85. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 216. 
 
 * Ibid., p. 216. (Quoted from the report of the Pennsylvania Bureau 
 of Mines.) 
 
462 Immigration and Labor 
 
 loss of 273 lives through the carelessness of " other persons," 
 is open to question. 1 Yet that statement of the Pennsyl- 
 vania report is the only direct statistical evidence in support 
 of the Commission's conclusion ''that the responsibility 
 for a majority of the accidents in coal mines rests with the 
 men injured. This being the case" continues the Com- 
 mission "it is evident that an inquiry as to the responsi- 
 bility of a given race for accidents may perhaps best be 
 answered by showing the extent to which its numbers are 
 sufferers from accidents.*' 2 
 
 Disinterested mining experts, however, do not accept the 
 apologetic theory of the mine operators as an "undisputed 
 fact." 
 
 At the summer meeting of the Mining Institute of 
 America, held in 1910, shortly after the Cherry Mine holo- 
 caust, the causes of mine fires were discussed in a paper, 
 from which the following is quoted : 
 
 In looking over the accounts of some of the mine fires which have 
 startled the general public more than others, I was forcibly struck with 
 three of them (Avondale, Hill Farm, and Cherry), especially in the 
 general aspect at least of the similarity of their cause and effect, and of 
 the cycle of years between each. The Avondale Mine was a single- 
 shaft opening. The structural material used in the shaft lining, parti- 
 tions, derrick, and breaker, was composed of wood. The fire originated 
 at the bottom of the shaft, caused by the carelessness of the furnace man 
 in lighting the furnace fire, thereby setting fire to the wooden partition, 
 etc. This fire occurred in the month of September, 1869, and in it 109 
 lives were lost. As you remember, no adequate means were at hand 
 with which to extinguish the fire. . . . The Cherry Mine'disaster . . . 
 originated at the No. 2 seam landing of the escapement shaft and was 
 
 1 Dr. John Randolph Haynes, Special Commissioner on Mining 
 Accidents of the State of California, in a paper read at the last annual 
 meeting of the American Association for Labor Legislation, at Washing- 
 ton, D. C, questioned the independence of State mining inspectors: 
 " They do not wish to lose their positions, which they are very likely 
 to do if they annoy the owners of coal mines, who very commonly 
 own the railroads which carry the coal, and enjoy intimate relations 
 with banks and other corporations that exercise quiet but effective 
 power in State politics." "A Federal Mining Commission," American 
 Labor Legislation Review, vol. ii, No. I, p. 145. * Ibid., p. 233. 
 
Work Accidents 463 
 
 caused by the ignition of hay from the flame of a crude, improvised, unpro- 
 tected illuminating contrivance. The flame from the hay was commu- 
 nicated to the overabundance of wood supporting material at the landing, 
 and adding thereto the inadequate means available to successfully deal 
 with afire of such magnitude, with the ill-judged actions of the inexperi- 
 enced men at the bottom, the trap was complete and the men caught 
 therein, so we have now to record the greatest and most disastrous mine 
 fire in the history of the coal-mining industry of this country, so far as 
 the loss of life is concerned. Two hundred and sixty -eight lives were 
 lost in the Cherry Mine disaster. 
 
 It has always appeared to me that the causes of mine fires were so 
 apparent to the thoughtful and intelligent mining men that their occur- 
 rence and their ill effects were unnecessary. . . . The prevention of 
 mine fires lies in the removal of the causes, which are well known, and the 
 knowledge of means and methods to be employed for their elimination, 
 being within the range and scope of the ability of the ordinary mine 
 official, the wonder is that they do happen. To secure freedom from 
 mine fires I believe lies almost entirely within the intelligently directed 
 administrative powers of the mine management, and in my opinion if the 
 mine officials are careful, alert, and capable, immunity from them can 
 be secured. . . . 
 
 Every coal mine should consist of two separate openings and one of 
 them should be used exclusively for an escapement. . . . The escape- 
 ment shaft, if over one hundred feet in depth, should be equipped with 
 safe and efficient hoisting apparatus. The structure at the hoisting 
 shaft should be built of steel, and the engine and power house should 
 be built of concrete, brick, or masonry; the shaft linings to be of con- 
 crete, and the shaft bottoms, if needing supports for the roof, should be of 
 steel I beams, concrete, or brickwork; doors between main shaft and 
 escapement shaft should be so located as to be easily accessible to the 
 workmen from all parts of the mine by convenient traveling ways, other 
 than those which lead directly to the bottom of the hoisting shaft; 
 mule stables, if not entirely prohibited in the mines, should be built 
 of incombustible material and illuminated with protected incandescent 
 electric lights; all oil, electric, and gasoline pump houses should be kept 
 free from combustible material, and be built of concrete, brickwork, or 
 masonry. When the main workings pf a mine have advanced five 
 thousand feet in length and the remaining extent of the property and 
 the other conditions warrant it, an auxiliary escapement opening should 
 be provided and equipped with efficient and necessary machinery; a water 
 system under sufficient pressure . . . should be installed at all important 
 mines, . . . and all parts and connections kept in first-class condition 
 and ready for use at all times; all electric cables or wires, etc., should be 
 well supported and insulated, and not allowed to come in contact with 
 
464 Immigration and Labor 
 
 combustible material. . . . A telephone system should be provided at 
 important mines so that communication can be had between persons 
 outside, and all important stations inside of them; refuge chambers, 
 efficiently constructed and equipped and conveniently located, should 
 be provided in all large and dangerous mines. 
 
 Mines should be provided with a powerful reversible fan, and it should 
 be placed on a separate shaft, cased in steel, and fitted with relief doors. 1 
 
 These details have been quoted in order to show that 
 effective prevention of accidents in mines presupposes a care- 
 fully planned equipment involving considerable expense. 
 A separate roadway for miners means additional tunneling 
 work. Two separate openings for every coal mine cost 
 twice as much as one. Refuge chambers require additional 
 excavation and construction work. Concrete or brick is 
 more expensive than wood, which is generally used as 
 structural material in coal mines. A powerful reversible 
 fan placed on a separate shaft cased in steel is another item 
 of expense ; so is a water system under sufficient pressure, 
 a telephone system, etc. All this is well known to mine 
 superintendents, "but they are pressed for dividends by the 
 presidents and their companies; the presidents are not 
 heartless, but they are pressed for dividends by their 
 directors who . . . are interested in the mines only* as a 
 matter of profit." 2 
 
 The dilemma of the mine superintendent was set forth 
 in a paper on "Mine Accident Prevention," which was 
 recently read before the Alabama Coal Operators' Associa- 
 tion by Mr. J. J. Rutledge, a geologist and mining engineer 
 of many years' experience, who has made his way from the 
 bottom up, beginning as assistant mine foreman and advan- 
 cing to the positions of mine manager and superintendent. 
 He has visited many of the important coal mines in this 
 country, and has been brought into close personal contact 
 with mine foremen and superintendents. He is of the 
 opinion that "the person who is the greatest factor in the pre- 
 
 '"Mine Fires," by Thomas K. Adams. Mines and Minerals, De- 
 cember, 1910. a Haynes, loc. cit., p. 145. 
 
Work Accidents 465 
 
 vention of mine accidents is the mine foreman or manager. 
 . . . He should never cancel any requisition for supplies 
 that are absolutely required. Perhaps the greatest abuse of 
 this sort is the cancellation of supplies which are required to 
 make ventilation more effective." But it is not unusual 
 that the foreman or manager "is handicapped or hindered 
 in his work by the failure to receive proper supplies or equip- 
 ment from his superiors." That he might "be encouraged 
 to demand the same and . . . be insured against possible loss 
 of employment by reason of his making such a demand . . . 
 the law should back him up in making such demands." 1 
 It is an undisputed fact that poor and defective methods 
 of ventilation largely increase the danger of gas explosion : 
 "An adequate air supply is not only required as a safeguard 
 against the accumulation of dangerous gases, but is pre- 
 requisite to the maintenance of the health of miners and 
 animals employed underground." 2 
 
 But the mine manager who is not "insured against pos- 
 sible loss of employment" will take his chances and cancel 
 requisitions for "supplies that are absolutely required." 
 These conditions naturally breed a spirit of carelessness 
 among mine officials, which is, according to expfert opinion, 
 "first among the causes of the high fatality rate in Ameri- 
 can mines." Such was the conclusion reached by three 
 European government experts, among them the Belgian 
 Inspector-General of Mines, who made an examination of 
 American mines upon the invitation of the United States 
 Government. By way of illustration, one of these experts 
 related the following incident: 
 
 While passing through a mine in West Virginia with a party carrying 
 both naked and safety lamps, he lifted his lamp toward the roof to test 
 for gas and was surprised to find it present in very dangerous quantities. 
 Turning to the mine superintendent, he remarked, " You should not 
 
 1 J. J. Rutledge: " Mine Accident Prevention." Mines and Minerals, 
 December, 1910. 
 
 * F. L. Hoffman: "Fatal Accidents in Coal Mines." Bulletin of the 
 United States Bureau of Labor, No. 90, p. 471. 
 
466 Immigration and Labor 
 
 allow naked lamps to be used in this mine." "Oh," replied the super- 
 intendent, easily, "we are installing a ventilating system that in a 
 few months will rid the mine entirely of gas and render the use of safety 
 lamps unnecessary." "Before that time arrives," protested the Euro- 
 pean expert, "your mine will be blown up." And this is precisely 
 what happened. The naked lamps were not excluded, the mine was 
 blown up a few weeks later, and hundreds of miners lost their lives. 
 ... No European mining superintendent would dream of taking such 
 chances as he foolishly took at the cost of so many lives; and, if he were 
 so inclined, the government inspector would not permit him to do so. 1 
 
 Mine explosions and mine fires impress the imagination 
 by the appalling destruction of lives in a single accident. 
 A great many more lives, however, are sacrificed under 
 ordinary circumstances in every-day accidents, which find 
 their way only into the statistical reports of State mine 
 inspectors, being too common to be noticed by the news- 
 papers. 
 
 Every advance in mining engineering within recent years 
 has had the effect of increasing the risks of the miner in the 
 United States. One of the original dangers in underground 
 coal mines is from falls of roof, which are the result, at 
 least in part, of insufficient timbering. This risk has been 
 considerably increased by the use of high explosives. 2 
 With the installation of improved mining machinery, ex- 
 posure to unguarded machines has been added to other 
 perils of mining. 3 Electrocution threatens the miner as a 
 result of the application of electricity to mining. The chief 
 inspector of coal mines for Pennsylvania gave warning of 
 this danger in his report for 1901 : 
 
 Electricity in various forms has been the cause of many of the 
 deaths in soft coal mines, either from the men coming in contact with 
 the electric trolley wire, or with the electric wire that carries the power 
 to the electric cutting machines. In my opinion, separate travelling 
 ways should be provided for the workman, when the haulage is done by 
 electricity.* 
 
 'Haynes, loc. cit., p. 143. * Eastman, loc. cit., pp. 38-39. 
 
 Hoffman, loc. cit., pp. 476-477- 4 Ibid., pp. 478-479. 
 
Work Accidents 467 
 
 When this recommendation was adopted in one Colorado 
 mine ten years later, the Engineering and Mining Journal 
 found the fact of sufficient interest as news to print the 
 following letter from a correspondent: 
 
 This mine has introduced a decided novelty in the form of a separate 
 roadway for the miners to enter and leave the workings, thus doing away 
 with the necessity of their travelling along the haulage-ways, and pro- 
 viding an additional avenue of escape. in time of danger. 1 
 
 The displacement of the mule by the cable car or electric 
 motor has been the source of a new danger to the life of the 
 miner. Many miners are killed by the running trains of 
 coal. This is, of course, clearly the result of their own 
 negligence: why do they travel in the haulage- way? The 
 fact is, however, that the man-entry and track are dark 
 from beginning to end and low, so that one would have to 
 travel in a stooping position all the way. The track is cov- 
 ered with loose slate and big chunks of coal. Therefore the 
 miners prefer the haulage entry, where there are occasional 
 lights, a smooth path to walk, and a higher roof. 2 Most of 
 these risks are humanly preventable, 3 and their continuance 
 is due to economic conditions beyond the control of the 
 mine worker, even with a perfect command of English. 
 
 The economic cause of the high rate of fatalities in 
 American coal mines was squarely stated by Dr. J. A. 
 Holmes, Director of the Bureau of Mines, in an address 
 delivered at the annual meeting of the National Civic 
 Federation in New York, November 23, 1909: 
 
 There can be no permanent industry without reasonable profits. 
 It is unjust and irrational that in this great and essential branch of 
 industry reasonable profits or even the payment of operating expenses 
 should be dependent upon met'wds involving unnecessary sacrifice of 
 human life. . . . Ruinous competition exists not only between the 
 operators in the same fields, but between the operators of one field as 
 against those in another field or in another state where different mining 
 laws and regulations are in force. This competition is ... forcing 
 
 1 The Engineering and Mining Journal, January 14, 1911, p. 135. 
 
 2 Eastman, loc. tit., pp. 38-39. a Ibid., p. 46. 
 
468 Immigration and Labor 
 
 even the larger operator to mine coal under conditions which he cannot 
 approve, but from which he finds no escape. . . . Each must live (or 
 succumb) by underbidding the other, which he can do only through 
 following the wasteful and unsafe mining methods which prevail in 
 this country to-day in spite of the desire of every operator, to improve 
 them. The American mine owner is as humane as the mine owner of 
 any other country, and he would like to follow every practice and use 
 every appliance for safety to be found in Great Britain, or France, or 
 Belgium, or Germany, or elsewhere, but he pays his miners higher 
 wages and, at the same time, receives for his coal at the mine half the 
 price received for similar coal by the operator in those countries. . . . 
 The ruinous competitive system upon which coal mining in the United 
 States is based at the present time should be changed and the price 
 paid for coal at the mines should be such as will permit and secure 
 safe and efficient mining mining unaccompanied by either this large 
 loss of life or waste of resources, mining which can have due regard 
 not only to the safety, but also to the health and comfort of the men 
 who toil underground. x 
 
 Thus in the opinion of the head of the bureau created 
 for the purpose of safeguarding the lives of the mine work- 
 ers, "unnecessary sacrifice of human life" is conditioned 
 by competition among mine operators. 
 
 According to the inspector-general of mines of Belgium 
 (quoted above), "similar dangerous conditions once existed 
 in France and Belgium, now the safest coal-mining countries 
 in the world/* but they were removed by stringent legisla- 
 tion and by an effective enforcement of the law. 2 In 
 Europe wooden shafts are not permitted, the maximum 
 amount of explosives to be used in one blast is limited by 
 law, all machinery must be properly guarded, etc. Dr. 
 Holmes believes that the adoption of similar regulations in 
 the United States would prevent three fourths of the present 
 
 'Joseph A. Holmes: "Coal Mine Accidents and their Prevention," 
 Thirty- Fifth Annual Report of the Chief Inspector of Mines of the State 
 of Ohio, 1909, pp. 126-128. 
 
 a Haynes, loc. cit., pp. 148, 150-151. Clarence Hall and Walter O. 
 Snelling: "Coal Mine Accidents: their Causes and Prevention." Bul- 
 letin of the United States Geological Survey, No. 333, p. 6. Eastman, loc. 
 cit., p. 46. Hoffman, loc. cit., pp. 476-477. 
 
Work Accidents 
 
 469 
 
 loss of life, 1 which implies that "the greatest number cf 
 accidents in bituminous coal mines" (contrary to the view 
 accepted by the immigration Commission), do not arise 
 from "the recklessness, ignorance, and inexperience of 
 employees." 
 
 This opinion is derived from the statistics of accidents in 
 the United States and foreign countries. The comparative 
 rates of fatal accidents in American and foreign coal mines 
 are shown graphically in Diagram XXV., reproduced from 
 
 DIAGRAM XXV. 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 3.5 
 
 
 
 3. 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 - 
 
 
 2J5 
 
 
 2.1 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 1.93 |. 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1.71 
 
 1.5 
 
 
 to 
 
 m 
 
 
 
 
 1.6 
 
 
 1.46 
 
 1 
 
 as 
 
 
 NITED STAT 
 
 1 
 
 ERMANY 
 
 *J 
 
 DC 
 
 
 i 
 
 -j 
 
 1 
 t 
 
 USTRIA 
 
 1 1 1 :i 4 
 
 iBblil 
 
 QC lo 1^- let <*j| 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 5 
 
 *f 
 
 2 tE 25 li a 
 
 XXV. Fatal accident rates in coal mines per 1000 workmen employed 
 in the United States and foreign countries. 
 
 the recent study of the Minnesota Bureau of Labor on the 
 subject of industrial accidents. * The rate of fatal accidents 
 in the United States is thrice as high as in France and 
 Belgium, which shows that two thirds of the fatal accidents 
 in the American mines could be prevented. Considering, 
 
 1 Haynes, loc. tit., p. 140. 
 
 Twelfth Biennial Report of the Bureau of Labor, Industries and Com- 
 merce of the State of Minnesota,, 1909-10, p. 203. 
 
470 Immigration and Labor 
 
 however, that the natural conditions in American mines 
 are more favorable for the safe extraction of coal than in 
 any other country in the world, x Dr. Holmes's estimate that 
 three fourths of all mining accidents are due to absence 
 of proper precautions is quite conservative. 
 
 The difference between the accident rate in the United 
 States and those in Austria and Russia deserves special 
 attention, a large percentage of American mine workers 
 being Austrian and Russian immigrants. The American 
 fatality rate is twice as high as the Austrian, Of course, 
 the popular explanation is, that the Austrians and Russians 
 employed in American mines do not understand the English 
 language, whereas in their home countries thev work under 
 the direction of foremen who speak their own languages. 
 In so far as the failure of foreign-born mine workers to 
 understand warnings and instructions given in the English 
 language may affect the rate of accidents in American mines, 
 the difference is clearly chargeable to the carelessness, not of 
 the mine workers, but of the mine operators who fail to pro- 
 vide competent foremen speaking the languages of their em- 
 ployees. In Prussia, where a large and growing percentage 
 of the coal miners are Poles, 2 the fatal accident rate is never- 
 theless 37 per cent below the average for the United States. J 
 
 1 United States Geological Survey, Bulletin No. 333, p. 13. The 
 European experts above referred to "unanimously reported that the 
 natural conditions in American mines were much better than in Europe. 
 They found, for example, that up to the present time Americans were 
 not operating in the very deep levels of four thousand feet and lower, 
 not uncommon in Europe, where the task of supplying fresh air and 
 getting rid of dangerous gases is very difficult. In America, also, only 
 thick seams more easily ventilated are, as yet, generally worked. . . . 
 Of late years, with the gradual exhaustion of higher levels, of the thicker 
 seams, and of the supplies of supporting timbers, conditions have come 
 to resemble more nearly those found in Europe, and it is for this reason 
 that the percentage of fatalities has so rapidly increased in the past 
 decade." Haynes, loc. cit. t pp. 141-142. 
 
 * See Chapter VIII., p. 182. The average for 1900-1904 in Prussia 
 was 2.06 per 1000 employees. 
 
 United States Geological Survey, Bulletin No. 333, p. 8. 
 
Work Accidents 471 
 
 This comparison may be pursued further. If it is true 
 that the rate of fatalities in the United States is increased 
 by the employment of immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe, it may be expected that the rate will be 
 higher in those States where the percentage of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans is higher among the coal miners. 
 The comparative numbers of lives lost per thousand em- 
 ployees and per one million tons of coal mined in the prin- 
 cipal mining States during the twenty-year period 1889- 
 1908 are shown on Diagram XXVI, the distance from left 
 to right representing the percentage of persons of Slavic 
 and Italian parentage among the miners in I9OO. 1 These 
 States produced, in 1908, 86.6 per cent of the total output 
 of bituminous coal in the United States. 2 
 
 We find the highest rate of fatal accidents per one million 
 tons mined, in Oklahoma, with 14 per cent of Southern and 
 Eastern European mine workers; next follow Tennessee 
 and Alabama, with I per cent and 2 per cent of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans respectively. On the other hand, 
 in Pennsylvania with 36 per cent, and Illinois with 22 
 per cent, the rate of accidents is much lower, and ap- 
 proximately the same as in Ohio with 9 per cent, and 
 Indiana with 5.5 per cent. The course of the other curve 
 is the same: West Virginia, Alabama, and Tennessee, with 
 small percentages of Southern and Eastern European mine 
 workers, have higher fatality rates per one thousand em- 
 ployees than Pennsylvania and Illinois with much larger 
 percentages of Southern and Eastern Europeans. 
 
 1 For rates of fatal accidents cf. Hoffman, loc cit., p. 452; the percent- 
 ages of miners of Southern and Eastern European parentage were 
 computed from XII. Census Report on Occupations, Table 41. The 
 figures are given in the Appendix, Table XXVII. The census classifica- 
 tion of breadwinners by occupation, nativity, and state makes no distinc- 
 tion between coal miners and metalliferous miners. This comparison 
 accordingly comprises only such States in which there are no metalli- 
 ferous mines, or the number of metalliferous miners is negligible, com- 
 pared with the number of coal miners. 
 
 3 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1910, Table 120, pp. 208-209. 
 
II 
 
 Si 
 
 sis 
 
 1 
 
 
 8.3 
 
 472 
 
Work Accidents 473 
 
 These comparisons are not invalidated by the increase 
 of the proportion of Southern and Eastern Europeans among 
 the coal miners since 1900. The investigation of the Immi- 
 gration Commission in 1900 found 64.3 per cent of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans among the coal miners of Penn- 
 sylvania, while the official statistics for West Virginia in 
 1908 showed 28.9 per cent of the same races 1 ; and yet the 
 average fatal accident rate per one thousand employees or 
 per one million tons in West Virginia was much higher 
 than in Pennsylvania. 
 
 The Immigration Commission lays great stress on the 
 fact that the percentage of fatalities among the foreign- 
 speaking miners in those two States is relatively higher than 
 among the English-speaking employees. This difference, 
 however, proves nothing without a further classification 
 of both language groups by occupation. The distribution 
 of the English-speaking and non-English-speaking mine 
 workers on the scale of occupations is not uniform, and there 
 is a wide range of variation in the degree of risk incident 
 to each occupation. The influence of the first factor will 
 be clear from the following. Machine runners and car 
 loaders work side by side in the mine. The machine runner 
 is the man who runs the mining machinery necessarily a 
 skilled miner; the car loader is a common laborer. And 
 yet we find that in 1899-1908 the proportion of native white 
 among machine runners who lost their lives in West Vir- 
 ginia was 80.8 per cent, while the proportion of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans among car loaders killed was 48.4 
 per cent; on the other hand, the proportion of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans among machine runners killed was 
 only 6.4 per cent, while the proportion of native white 
 among car loaders killed was 24.3 per cent. 2 It would be 
 absurd to infer from these figures that the Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans were more experienced and more careful 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 226, Table 140; p. 
 228, Table 143. 
 
 > Jloffnjan, he cit., p. 640. 
 
474 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 than the native white, when the truth is that there are few 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans among the machine 
 runners and few native white among the car loaders. In- 
 asmuch, however, as there are several loaders to one machine 
 runner, more loaders are killed than machine runners. The 
 effect of these arithmetical aberrations upon the general 
 average is to swell the ratio of Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans to the total of fatal accidents. 
 
 The effect of the nature of the risk upon fatal accidents 
 by lace and nativity is shown in Table 131. 
 
 TABLE 131. 
 
 NUMBER AND PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF FATAL ACCIDENTS IN COAL 
 MINES OF WEST VIRGINIA BY PRINCIPAL CAUSES AND NATIVITY OF 
 PERSONS KILLED, 1899-1908, AND PER CENT DISTRIBUTION OF 
 EMPLOYEES BY NATIVITY, I9OO. 1 
 
 Race or nativity 
 
 Per cent of 
 employees 
 
 Falling coal, 
 slate, etc. 
 
 Explosions 
 
 Other causes 2 
 
 Number 
 
 s 
 
 8 
 1 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Number 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Native white 
 
 46.3 
 21.8 
 
 3-o 
 28.9 
 
 392 
 207 
 
 68 
 285 
 
 41.2 
 
 21.8 
 
 7-1 
 29.9 
 
 246 
 130 
 
 59 
 
 387 
 
 30.0 
 15-8 
 
 7-1 
 47.1 
 
 194 
 
 84 
 
 8 
 61 
 
 55-9 
 24.2 
 
 2-3 
 17-6 
 
 Negro 
 
 Northern and 
 Western Europe. . . 
 Eastern and Southern 
 Europe 
 
 Total 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 952 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 822 
 
 100.0 
 
 347 
 
 100.0 
 
 
 If the "relative number of fatalities among the employees 
 of a given race or group of races" can "serve as a valuable 
 indication of the extent to which the high death-rate in the 
 mines is to be attributed to the employment of men by 
 
 1 Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, No. 90, Table XX., p. 646. Reports 
 of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p.~228, Table 143. 
 
 * Cars (inside and outside) , motors and machinery, electrocution and 
 falling into shafts. 
 
Work Accidents 475 
 
 that race or group, " J then the following conclusions logically 
 follow from the preceding table: 
 
 1 . While the recent immigrants contribute no more than 
 their proportionate share of fatalities from falling coal, 
 slate, etc., the high death-rate from explosions is attribut- 
 able to them. On the other hand native Americans con- 
 tribute less than their quota of accidents from these causes. 
 
 2. The older immigrants from Northern and Western 
 Europe contribute twice their share of fatalities from falls 
 of roofs and explosions, which indicates that the employ- 
 ment of older immigrants is a menace to the safety of the 
 men inside the mines. 
 
 3. The native white contribute more than their quota 
 of fatalities from cars, motors, machinery, and contact with 
 electric wires, whereas the Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 contribute considerably less than their quota, which indi- 
 cates that the high death-rate from those causes is at- 
 tributable to the employment of men of native American 
 stock. 
 
 4. The replacement of native Americans by Southern 
 and Eastern European immigrants who apparently show 
 greater aptitude for handling complicated modern machin- 
 ery than native Americans, would tend to reduce the fatality 
 rate from cars, motors, machinery, and electric shocks. 
 On the other hand the displaced American mechanics 
 could be employed to advantage as common laborers in 
 the mines, which would tend to reduce the fatal accident 
 rate from falling roofs and explosions. 
 
 The palpable absurdity of these conclusions proves that 
 the premises from which they are deduced are untenable. 
 The low percentage of Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 among the sufferers from accidents due to machinery, 
 motors, etc., merely indicates that they do not come in 
 contact with these death-dealing agencies as often as 
 Americans. Similarly, the lower ratio of native white 
 among the sufferers from falling roofs and explosions is 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 233. 
 
476 Immigration and Labor 
 
 attributable to the fact that a large proportion among them 
 are employed in supervisory positions, where they are not 
 exposed to the ordinary risks incident to working under- 
 ground. 
 
 It is sought to deduce a causal connection between the 
 increase of the fatal accident rate and the employment of 
 recent immigrants from their ignorance of mining conditions 
 which exposes them to greater danger. If this be so, it is 
 an argument, not against immigration, but against the 
 development of the coal mining industry. It is evident that 
 if the mining industry is to grow apace with the development 
 of the country, new men must continually be engaged. No 
 one is born with mining experience, even in the United 
 States, and there is no other place where mining experience 
 can be gained except in a mine. The danger resulting from 
 allowing inexperienced men, whether native or foreign- 
 born, to work in a coal mine merely emphasizes the need 
 of providing by law for the employment of a sufficient 
 proportion of experienced miners to supervise the work of 
 new employees. x So dangerous, however, are the working 
 conditions in American mines that, according to Mr. 
 Hoffman, "mine experience, even of considerable length, 
 is not necessarily a protective factor." 2 His opinion rests 
 upon a classification of accidents by occupation and length 
 of experience. It appears that in every occupation the 
 majority of those who were killed in West Virginia in 1899- 
 
 1 Says Mr. John Laing, chief of the West Virginia Department of 
 Mines, in a letter to the Immigration Commission: "In our large mines 
 where in the past labor was turned loose to shoot coal, load coal, and 
 care for themselves, we now have an officer known as 'assistant mine 
 foreman* employed to every thirty-five men, who works in the mine 
 and whose specific duty is to see that all coal is properly mined, that 
 all places are timbered, that a system of ventilation is properly brought 
 forward, etc., before a miner be permitted to do blasting of any 
 kind." Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 238. 
 
 3 "It is significant," says Mr. Hoffman, "that there should have 
 been 43 deaths of men who had been at work from 10-14 years, 
 13 deaths of men with 15-19 years of mine experience and 1 1 deaths of 
 men with 20 or more years' experience." Loc. cit., p. 485. 
 
Work Accidents 
 
 477 
 
 1908 had an experience of not less than one year, and in 
 some occupations one of more than five years, e. g., fire 
 bosses 100 per cent; track layers 60.8 per cent; machine 
 runners 59.5 per cent, etc. Among the miners, the most 
 numerous and exposed class, 39.7 per cent had an experience 
 of over five years. x 
 
 The preceding classification deals with length of experi- 
 ence, without regard to race or nationality. It might be 
 argued that the Southern and Eastern Europeans are handi- 
 capped by ignorance of the English language even after 
 years of employment in the mines and possibly swell the 
 numbers of victims with long experience. This supposition 
 is dismissed by the West Virginia statistics in which the 
 accidents are classified by nativity and length of experience, 
 as shown in Table 132: 
 
 TABLE 132. 
 
 NUMBER AND PER CENT OF TOTAL ACCIDENTS TO COAL MINERS, CLASSIFIED 
 
 BY NATIVITY AND LENGTH OF EXPERIENCE IN WEST VIRGINIA, 
 
 1899-1908. 3 
 
 
 
 Numbe 
 
 r 
 
 
 Per cent 
 
 
 Length of experience 
 
 English- 
 speaking 
 white 
 
 Southern and 
 Eastern 
 European 
 
 1 
 
 i! 
 
 IP 
 
 Southern and 
 Eastern 
 Europeans 
 
 ! 
 
 Under I year 
 
 124 
 
 ISO 
 
 66 
 
 18 i 
 
 24. 4 
 
 22.8 
 
 15 years 
 
 221 
 
 ^06 
 
 IJC 
 
 \2 2 
 
 *q~4 
 
 40.6 
 
 1Q.8 
 
 
 14.1 
 
 1 6O 
 
 1 08 
 
 4Q.7 
 
 i^y.w 
 26.O 
 
 ^7.4 ' 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 686 
 
 616 
 
 280 
 
 IOO O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 IOO.O 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 This table shows that experience of the mine workers 
 counts for very little in fatal accidents: one half of all 
 English-speaking mine workers had had an experience of 
 
 1 Hoffman, loc. cit., Table XVII., p. 643, 
 d., Table XIX., p. 645. 
 
478 Immigration and Labor 
 
 more than five years when they lost their lives. Of the 
 Southern and Eastern Europeans killed, one fourth had 
 worked more than five years in the mines and three fourths 
 more than one year. The smaller percentage of Southern 
 and Eastern Europeans who lost their lives after an experi- 
 ence of more than five years cannot be taken as proof that 
 inexperience was the cause of death in all other cases: it 
 must be borne in mind that most of the Southern and East- 
 ern European miners in West Virginia are recent immigrants, 
 who for this arithmetical reason alone must contribute a 
 larger number to the death roll of persons with brief experi- 
 ence. If it is sought to explain the prevalence of more 
 recent immigrants among the victims of accidents by their 
 negligence, due to inexperience, it must follow as a corollary 
 that the higher percentage of miners of long experience 
 among the English-speaking victims proves them to be 
 twice as careless or as ignorant as the Southern and Eastern 
 Europeans. This assumption does not agree, however, 
 with the fact that the percentage of recent employees among 
 the victims of accidents is approximately the same for 
 every language or race group. It is clear that the knowl- 
 edge of the English language gives the new mine worker 
 scarcely greater immunity from accident than that which 
 the law of chance allows to the non-English-speaking miner. 
 The cause of accidents in coal mines is not philological, 
 but technological. 
 
 Withal, it is an undeniable fact that the fatal accident 
 rate has increased in the bituminous coal mines of the 
 United States within the last twenty years, simultaneously 
 with the increasing numbers of Slavs and Italians employed 
 in the mines. This coincidence is accepted as sufficient 
 proof that the increasing employment of Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans in coal mines has been the cause of the 
 increase in the fatal accident rate. This explanation is 
 contradicted, however, by the sfatistics of accidents in 
 the anthracite coal mines of Pennsylvania, for which there 
 are data going as far back as 1870. In 1909, 60 per cent 
 
I 
 
 479 
 
480 Immigration and Labor 
 
 of the inside employees in the anthracite mines were of 
 the non-English-speaking races. 1 As shown on Diagram 
 XXVII, 2 the greatest relative numbers of fatal accidents 
 were recorded back in 1870-1874, when the employees 
 were all English-speaking. The lowest rate per one million 
 tons mined is reported for the year 1903, and the next 
 lowest for the year 1909. 
 
 In the face of this fact, the increase in the number of 
 recent immigrant employees cannot stand as an explanation 
 of the increase of the accident rate in bituminous mines. 
 The European mining experts, mentioned before, lay stress 
 upon the " gradual exhaustion of higher levels, of the thicker 
 seams, and of the supplies of supporting timbers, . . . 
 and it is for this reason (they hold) that the percentage of 
 fatalities has so rapidly increased in the past decade." 3 
 
 No doubt "contributory negligence" on the part of the 
 Southern and Eastern European may figure as a factor in 
 many accidents. It is claimed, e. g., by American and 
 English-speaking miners, that the lives of the mine workers 
 are endangered by the carelessness of the recent immigrants 
 whose "desire . . . for large earnings . . . leads them to 
 neglect to take the proper measures . . . relative to tim- 
 bering and other precautions, for the reason that these 
 measures require the loss of time from their productive 
 work and the consequent decrease in earnings." 4 This 
 claim is nothing but the outworn common-law defence of 
 "negligence of fellow-servant," in an employer's liability 
 action. From the modern point of view the employer's 
 duty to furnish his employees a safe place of work is not 
 discharged by leaving the necessary timbering to be done 
 by volunteers for the common good without extra compen- 
 sation. It is his duty to hire special men for that work and 
 to keep the mine safe at his own expense. Be it as it may, 
 
 1 Report of the Department of Mines of Pennsylvania, 1909, Part I. 
 pp. 25-26. a The figures will be found in the Appendix, Table XXVIII. 
 
 * Haynes, loc. cit., p. 142. 
 
 * Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 6, p. 652. 
 
Work Accidents 481 
 
 it is well to remember, however, that in those days when 
 there were no "ignorant foreigners" to whom the responsi- 
 bility for mine accidents could be shifted, it was the "reck- 
 lessness" of the English-speaking miners 1 that was to 
 blame. As far back as 1875, a Pennsylvania mine inspector 
 said in his report: "I am sorry to have to report that a 
 majority of the accidents that occur in the coal mines are 
 the result of recklessness of the workmen themselves." 2 
 This comment was as general in the early reports of the 
 Pennsylvania state mine inspectors, according to Dr. 
 Roberts, as in the recent reports quoted by the Immigration 
 Commission. It is evident that an American farmer boy 
 who for the first time goes down into a mine is as incapable 
 of a proper appreciation of the dangers of mining as a recent 
 Slav immigrant. But even an experienced miner faced 
 every day of his life with the "one universal characteristic" 
 of American mining conditions "the criminal disregard of 
 the considerations of safety" 3 at length comes to feel that 
 "a man may as well pass in his checks that way as any 
 other." 4 If he is to continue as a miner, he must develop 
 a frame of mind akin to that of a soldier in war-time. While 
 carelessness on the part of the miners may be a contri- 
 butory cause in many accidents, the "carelessness" itself is, 
 as Dr. Roberts put it a "psychological effect of accidents. " s 
 In the iron and steel mills there is the same disposition 
 as in coal mining to shift the responsibility for accidents to 
 the ignorance of the "Hunkie." Speaking of the "per- 
 sonal factor" in industrial accidents, Miss Eastman sub- 
 ordinates it to "the pressure and speed at which the plant 
 is run, an expression of the employ er's direct financial 
 interest in the output." 
 
 One of the older and wiser mill superintendents in the Pittsburgh 
 District told me [says she], that the one greatest cause of danger in 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, p. 232. 
 Roberts, loc. cit., p. 154. * Haynes, loc. cit. t p. 148. 
 
 * Words of a miner quoted from the report of a Pennsylvania mine 
 inspector, Roberts, loc. cit. t p. 154. s Ibid, 
 
482 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the steel mills is the tremendous rush of the work. "In the mills in 
 England," he said, "they begin to work about 6, stop at 8:30 for forty- 
 five minutes for the men to get breakfast; stop again at I for an hour 
 for the men to get dinner, and stop again at 5 130 for half an hour. At 
 these periods everything stops. The machinery is quiet. This is the 
 reason why the English mills do not produce as much steel in the same 
 length of time as the American mills. Here the machinery never stops. 
 Another shift is always ready and waiting to step into the place of the shift 
 that is leaving. Not a moment is lost. If a mill stops three minutes 
 for repairs, or for any other cause, a detailed report of this must be 
 made by the man in charge. If this happens two or three times under 
 one man, the matter will be taken up with a question as to his efficiency. 
 Under this kind of a drive, how can anybody be careful? " 
 
 When we read then, of a man who went up to make repairs without 
 stopping the crane, or of a man who tried to throw a belt without slow- 
 ing down the shaft, we must not lay the resulting accident unquestion- 
 ingly to his own personal, ill-considered haste. Perhaps he was but a 
 part of a great machine going too fast for safety. Every man in the 
 process must keep the pace of the whole. He can no more go his own 
 gait than a spoke in a wheel can go its own gait. * 
 
 But the Southern and Eastern European is charged with 
 more than ignorant carelessness or passive acquiescence 
 in dangerous conditions, the very existence of such con- 
 ditions "has been due to ... his tractability or sub- 
 serviency": 
 
 When the older employees have found unsafe and insanitary working 
 conditions prevailing in the mines and industrial establishments, and 
 have protested, the recent immigrant employees, usually through ignor- 
 ance of mining or other working methods, have manifested a willing- 
 ness to accept the alleged unsatisfactory condition. 2 
 
 As an illustration of such ineffective "protests," the 
 commission cites a case where an American miner was 
 discharged for refusing to work in a chamber which was in 
 need of timbering, and was replaced by a foreigner. 3 Similar 
 examples could, doubtless, be multiplied at will, considering 
 the general disregard for safety in coal mines. Such indi- 
 
 1 Eastman, loc. tit., pp. 64, 85, 94. 
 
 9 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 501. 
 
 *Ibid. t vol. 6, p. 241. 
 
Work Accidents 
 
 483 
 
 vidual objections, however, scarcely amount to a "protest." 
 If the English-speaking miners had shown a disposition to 
 "protest" against dangerous working conditions, it cer- 
 tainly must have found some expression in their strikes. 
 We learn that during the twenty-year period from 1881 
 to 1900, there occurred 2515 strikes in the coal and coke 
 industry, involving 14,575 establishments. Of the latter 
 number there were nine (p) in which strikes were declared 
 against dangerous working conditions. 1 These figures con- 
 clusively prove that the American miners made no concerted 
 protest against dangerous working conditions even in the 
 early *8o's, when the Southern and Eastern Europeans 
 employed in the mines were but a handful. 
 
 To what extent,if at all, individual objectionsof the "older 
 employees" would have been effective in advancing the 
 introduction of better working conditions, in the absence 
 of Southern and Eastern European immigrant employees, 
 can be judged by a comparison with another extra-hazard- 
 ous industry, viz., steam railroads, in which the proportion 
 of non-English-speaking employees is very small.* 
 
 1 Sixteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, pp. 352-353, 
 480-481. The objects for which these strikes were ordered were as 
 follows: 
 
 
 Number of estab- 
 lishments 
 
 Succeeded 
 
 For better ventilation 
 
 A 
 
 i 
 
 The same and for repair of machinery 
 For change of machinery 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 Against use of electrical mining machines 
 without jacketed motors . ... 
 
 I 
 
 
 For company to have roadway in mine 
 sprinkled 
 
 I 
 
 
 For enforcement of mining laws concerning 
 the placing of timbers . . 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 According to the census of 1900, the ratio of non-English-speaking 
 workmen employed on the railroads was only 7.5 per cent. Reports of 
 (he Immigration Commission, vol. i, pp. 821-829. 
 
484 Immigration and Labor 
 
 There is a marked distinction in this respect between 
 different classes of railroad employees. The trainmen are 
 as a rule, English-speaking, the Slavs, Hungarians, and 
 Italians being employed mainly on construction work. 
 In Diagram XXVIII. are plotted the accident rates per 1000 
 employees in bituminous and anthracite coal mines and on 
 railroads, for the twenty-year period from 1889 to 1908. l 
 The accident rate for all railway employees is not much 
 lower than the rate for coal miners. But the fatal accident 
 rate among trainmen is a great deal higher and has been 
 steadily increasing since 1894. 
 
 The number of accidents resulting in personal injuries 
 to railroad employees is still greater. In 1891-1909 it 
 varied from one in every thirty-three, to one in every 
 seventeen employees. The ratio of injured trainmen 
 varied during the same period from one in every twelve, 
 to one in eight. It stood at the last figure in 1906-1908 
 and declined to one in nine during the year 1909.* This 
 means that in nine years' service every trainman has a 
 probability of one hundred per cent to sustain personal 
 injuries. 
 
 The ratio of native Americans to all railroad employees 
 killed in work accidents, according to available informa- 
 tion, was 72 per cent in the Pittsburgh district, 3 and 
 62.8 per cent in Illinois; the proportion of those who suffered 
 personal injuries in Illinois was 66.6 per cent. 4 The 
 trainmen who run the greatest risk of death, or personal 
 injury, are all English-speaking and cannot be replaced by 
 non-English-speaking immigrants. Strike statistics show 
 that the employees in all industries combined under the 
 head of "transportation" struck for 212 different causes 
 
 1 The figures on which this diagram is based arc given in the Appendix, 
 Table XXIX. 
 
 a Statistical Abstract of the United Stales, 1910, Table 181, p. 284. 
 
 Eastman, loc. cit. t p. 14, Table 3; number of native Americans 
 89, out of a total of 123 killed in accidents. 
 
 * Fifteenth Biennial Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics of Illinois, 
 pp. 161, 251. 
 
a 
 fi 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 - g 
 
 "\W -r 
 
486 Immigration and Labor 
 
 in 3436 establishments, but the number of establishments 
 in which strikes were declared against unsafe machinery and 
 other dangers incident to employment was only seven. 1 
 
 This comparison may be extended to all classes of em- 
 ployment, loss of life and limb being an incident rather 
 than an accident of modern industry. The Sixteenth 
 Annual Report of the United States Commissioner of Labor 
 enumerates 1422 different causes of strikes for the twenty- 
 year period 1891-1900. The total number of establishments 
 which were affected by strikes during that period was 
 117,509. The number among them where strikes were de- 
 clared against unsafe machinery and other dangers incident to 
 employment was only eighty-three. 2 
 
 These figures testify that "acquiescence in dangerous 
 and unsanitary working conditions " is the general attitude 
 of organized and unorganized workers in labor disputes. 
 This apparent indifference cannot be explained by the 
 obstruction of the Southern and Eastern Europeans be- 
 cause the majority of the wage-earners as late as 1900 
 were of native birth. 3 It may reasonably be assumed that 
 organized labor does not feel strong enough to enforce 
 demands which would involve large outlays by employers 
 for safe equipment and other improvements. The indi- 
 vidual workman realizes that it would be quixotic on his 
 part to "protest" singly against evils which organized 
 labor is powerless to remedy. 
 
 1 Sixteenth Annual Report of the Commissioner of Labor, Table X. pp. 
 510-513. *Ibid., Table XI, pp. 519-541- 
 
 Hourwich, loc. cit., p. 327, Table VIII. 
 
PART IV 
 
 CONCLUSION 
 
 CHAPTER XXIII 
 
 PROBABLE EFFECTS OF RESTRICTION A FORECAST 
 
 IT was recognized by the Immigration Commission that the 
 industrial expansion of the preceding twenty years would 
 have been impossible without "the new immigration." 
 But the Commission held "a slow expansion of industry" 
 preferable to "immigration of laborers of low standards." 1 
 The Commission accordingly recommended that "a sufficient 
 number be debarred to produce a marked effect upon the 
 present supply of unskilled labor." 2 
 
 What is "a sufficient number"? A learned advocate of 
 restriction, Prof. Fairchild, referring to the period from 
 December, 1907, to August, 1908, when emigration exceeded 
 immigration by 124,124, finds that "this figure is almost 
 infinitesimal compared to the total mass of the American 
 working people or to the amount of unemployment at a normal 
 time, 1 ' The net result of the emigration movement of those 
 nine months was tantamount to a prohibition of immigra- 
 tion, yet it had "a very trifling palliative effect." 3 
 
 The slowing down of the pace of industrial development 
 must necessarily curtail the opportunities for advancement 
 of the wage-earners who are already here. 4 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, p. 45. 2 Ibid., p. 47. 
 
 Henry Pratt Fairchild: "Immigration and Crises," The American 
 Economic Review, December, 1911, p. 758. 
 
 4 The skilled crafts whose organizations were urging the adoption 
 of the recommendation of the Commission for the exclusion of unskilled 
 immigrants were apparently willing to swallow the recommendation 
 in favor of legislation that would facilitate the importation of skilled 
 labor under contract. (Reports of the Immigration Commission, 
 vol, i, p. 47-) 
 
 487 
 
488 Immigration and Labor 
 
 On the other hand, the unemployed could gain nothing 
 from a slow growth of industry. In times of rapid indus- 
 trial expansion the demand for labor is more active than 
 in times of industrial stagnation. Inasmuch as unem- 
 ployment is not due to an absolute oversupply of labor, 
 but results from seasonal and cyclical variations in the 
 general demand for labor, as well as from variations in 
 the demands of individual employers, it is clear that these 
 causes could not be removed by reducing the supply of 
 labor. If the industries of the United States can furnish 
 steady employment all year round to eighty per cent of all 
 wage-earners and in times of maximum activity to ninety- 
 five per cent, 2 but must have the full one hundred per cent 
 ready on call, there being no agency for dovetailing the de- 
 mands of scattered individual employers, these ratios will 
 not be affected by the scale of national production. 
 
 If instead of letting the number of factory workers grow 
 to seven million by 1909, the law had kept it at 5,600,000, 
 as it had been in 1904, i.e., twenty per cent below the 1909 
 figure, the industrial reserve of twenty per cent would not 
 have been wiped out, but would have only been smaller 
 in proportion. Yet the 1,120,000 irregularly employed 
 in 1904 exerted the same economic pressure on the 
 4,480,000 who were employed all year around, as the 
 1,400,000 on the 5,600,000 in 1909. The problem of the five 
 per cent irreducible minimum of unemployed was no less 
 serious when they were only 280,000 in 5,600,000, than when 
 they grew to be 350,000 in 7,000,000. The mere exclu- 
 sion of unskilled immigrants, and even of all immigrants, 
 will not provide employment for all masons and carpenters 
 in the winter, or for the full winter force of a Wisconsin 
 logging camp in the summer. Nor will the restriction of 
 immigration revolutionize the world of fashion, so as to 
 permit of the filling of orders for ladies' garments out of 
 
 *A11 figures in this example are merely estimates based upon the 
 statistics of the XII. and the XIII. Census. They are used only for 
 purposes of illustration. 
 
Probable Effects of Restriction A Forecast 489 
 
 season. In order to provide regular employment for the 
 industrial reserve, all industries would have to be run upon 
 a common time schedule, like railway trains are run on 
 connecting lines. No plan of such a reorganization of 
 industry has as yet been proposed that would be acceptable 
 to all advocates of immigration restriction, let alone the 
 proprietors of half a million independent mining, manu- 
 facturing, and mercantile establishments. It is hardly 
 reasonable to expect a systematic adjustment of business 
 activity on such a gigantic scale to grow up spontaneously 
 from a purely negative measure shutting out immigration. 
 As a theoretical proposition, it seems quite plausible 
 that the exclusion of "a sufficient number" of immigrants 
 "to produce a marked effect upon the supply of unskilled 
 labor" must force employers to pay scarcity rate of wages. 
 It is needless, however, to indulge in abstract speculation 
 on the possible effects of a reduced supply of unskilled 
 immigrant labor, when such a condition actually exists in 
 the United States throughout the agricultural sections. 
 Few immigrants seek employment on the farms. At the 
 census of 1900 the total number of Southern and Eastern 
 European male farm laborers in the United States was only 
 3 7, 40 1. 1 The number of all foreign-born male farm laborers 
 had actually decreased from 1890 to i9oo. 2 Moreover, there 
 is a constant stream of native labor from the farms to the 
 cities, which has led to an actual decrease of the rural 
 population in many agricultural counties. Farmers gen- 
 erally complain of scarcity of farm labor during the agri- 
 cultural season. Nevertheless, the wages of farm laborers 
 are lower than the wages of unskilled laborers in mines and 
 mills, where the proportion of recent immigrants is rapidly 
 increasing. Scarcity of labor has not forced the farmer to 
 pay scarcity wages, but has merely retarded the growth of 
 farming. In many places the area under cultivation has 
 actually decreased. On the other hand, the problem how 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. I, Table A, pp. 821-829. 
 
 2 Occupations, XII. Census, Table XXXIV, p. cviii. 
 
490 Immigration and Labor 
 
 to increase production with the same supply of labor has 
 been solved by labor-saving machinery. The shutting- 
 out of unskilled immigrants would have similar effects in 
 manufacturing and mining. The labor that would thus be 
 displaced would form one substitute for immigration. 
 
 The coal mines of Alabama and other Southern States 
 which have failed to attract immigrants utilize the labor 
 of farmers and their sons. The 2,300,000 tenant-farmers 
 in particular offer great possibilities as an industrial re- 
 serve available during the winter months when the de- 
 mand for labor in the coal mines is most active. The farm 
 being their main source of subsistence, they are able and 
 willing to offer their labor during the idle winter months 
 more cheaply than freshly-landed immigrants. The efforts 
 of trade-union organizers among this class of English- 
 speaking workers have met with scant success. With the 
 farmer who works in a mine during the winter months, 
 the dominating interest is his farm, whereas his interest 
 in his employment is but transitory. He may not return 
 to the mine the next winter; he accordingly expects no 
 benefit from an eventual gain in wages, whereas a pro- 
 tracted strike may deprive him of his earnings which are 
 needed immediately to pay interest on a mortgage or to 
 buy a machine. He is therefore reluctant to enter into a 
 labor contest. The substitution of the cheap labor of the 
 American farmer for the labor of the Slav or Italian immi- 
 grant would tend to weaken the unions and to keep down 
 wages. 
 
 The discontinuance of fresh supplies of immigrant labor 
 for the cotton mills of New England would give a new 
 impetus to the development of the cotton industry in the 
 South, where there is an abundant supply of child labor. 
 The shortage of immigrant labor could also be made up for in 
 part by the available reserve of cheap female labor. 
 
 The employment of all these, substitutes for regular 
 wage-earners certainly has its limitations. Summer is the 
 most active season in many manufacturing industries. 
 
Probable Effects of Restriction A Forecast 491 
 
 Other industries are localized and cannot spread out to 
 agricultural districts. But there is in the United States, 
 as in all industrial countries, a steady flow of labor from 
 rural to urban districts. In the absence of immigration 
 of unskilled laborers the depopulation of the rural districts 
 would be accelerated. A stimulated movement of labor 
 from the farm to the factory must act as a drawback on the 
 growth of farming, and the prices of foodstuffs would rise 
 in consequence, which would tend to offset the advantages 
 to the wage-earners from a possible rise of wages. 
 
 Still, should all the substitutes for immigrant labor prove 
 inadequate for the needs of the employers, it does not 
 necessarily follow that scarcity prices would rule in the 
 American labor market. It must be borne in mind that 
 capital is international. 
 
 Billions of American capital are already invested in 
 Mexican and other foreign undertakings. At present this 
 is but a minor item compared with the profits of American 
 industries annually reinvested at home. If, however, a 
 scarcity of labor were created in the United States, more 
 American capital would seek investment abroad. Instead 
 of investing their profits in new mines and mills in the United 
 States, American capitalists would export their money to 
 build up new enterprises in countries with cheap labor. 
 
 The increased investment of American capital in the 
 industrial development of foreign countries with cheap 
 labor must eventually react upon labor conditions in the 
 United States. Certain of the most important American 
 industries depend in part upon the export trade. At present 
 the great smelting works of New Jersey import ore from 
 Mexico and employ Slav immigrants to smelt and refine it 
 into lead and copper, a great deal of which is then exported 
 to Europe. Should the immigration of Slav laborers be 
 barred the lead and copper producers could accommodate 
 themselves to the situation by erecting plants in Mexico and 
 exporting the refined lead and copper directly to London. 
 Such a plan would not be a new departure in the world of 
 
492 Immigration and Labor 
 
 industry. American, English, French, Belgian, and German 
 manufacturers in the past found it more profitable to estab- 
 lish factories in Russia than to export their products to that 
 country. A scarcity of labor in the United States would 
 induce many American manufacturers to extend that policy. 
 
 Such an emigration of American capital would materially 
 affect the export trade of the United States and eventually 
 throw out of employment a number of American wage- 
 earners dependent upon that trade. 
 
 It is evident that while restriction of immigration can 
 limit the supply of labor, it is powerless to prevent a cor- 
 responding limitation of the demand for labor. 
 
 The Immigration Commission believed that "a slow ex- 
 pansion of industry," in the absence of "the immigration 
 of laborers of low standards," would raise "the American 
 standard of wages." Yet the Commission did not explain 
 how a mere Platonic desire to maintain a high standard of 
 living could of itself raise the rates of wages, unless the 
 relation of demand and supply in the labor market were 
 favorable to the wage-earner. The recent crisis has fur- 
 nished a practical illustration bearing upon this point. 
 When the operations of the steel mills were reduced, a 
 great many men were laid off. The companies, however, 
 offered their skilled men positions as laborers. 1 Neither 
 their high American standard of living, nor their high 
 standard of wages, nor their efficiency enabled them to 
 insist upon higher wages than those which had been paid 
 to unskilled laborers before the crisis. "A slow expansion 
 of industry" is synonymous with an inactive demand for 
 labor, and it is an elementary maxim of Political Economy 
 that an inactive demand for labor is unfavorable to in- 
 creases in wages. 
 
 1 "The few unskilled places that were open were filled by Americans 
 who were normally skilled workmen, but who at the time of the depres- 
 sion were compelled to take any kind of-work they could get. "Reports 
 of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, pp. 39, 40. 
 
 "Skilled American employees . . . were glad to turn to unskilled 
 occupations at twelve to fifteen cents an hour." Ibid., p. 597. 
 
CHAPTER XXIV 
 
 THE LESSONS OP THE WAR 
 
 THE World War offered an opportunity to test the effects 
 of restriction of immigration under the most favorable 
 conditions. During the war immigration was reduced to a 
 very low level. Departing aliens at times outnumbered both 
 the newcomers and returning immigrants. Though the out- 
 break of the war was followed by a year of industrial depres- 
 sion in this country, the United States soon became the chief 
 producer of war supplies for the Allied nations. Beginning 
 with the spring of 1916 the supply of labor in the United 
 States fell short of the demand in the labor market. The 
 entrance of the United States into the war withdrew more 
 than two million workers from industry. The government 
 assumed the function of regulating wages in the leading 
 industries, with the co-operation of the officers of the Amer- 
 ican Federation of Labor. Prominent men of avowed labor 
 sympathies were placed at the head of the War Labor Board. 
 If the economic condition of the American wage earner can 
 be improved by suspension of immigration, here was the 
 opportunity to observe its beneficial effects. 
 
 Indeed, the final report of the Commission on Industrial 
 Relations, prepared by Mr. Basil M. Manly, Director of 
 Research and Investigation, contains the following state- 
 ment: "The great diminution of immigration as a result of 
 the European war, has already begun to show its salutary 
 effects." l The report does not specify the particulars in 
 which these "salutary effects" had manifested themselves 
 by August 9, 1915, which is its official date. It baldly asserts 
 that the "evidence presented to the Commission" warrants 
 
 1 Industrial Relations: Final Report and Testimony, vol. i, p. 144 
 
494 Immigration and Labor 
 
 the conclusion "that the enormous influx of immigrants dur- 
 ing the past twenty-five years has been the largest single factor 
 in preventing the wage scale from rising as rapidly as food 
 prices." l The evidence was not published by the Commis- 
 sion; reference is only made in the Director's letter of sub- 
 mittal to reports presented to the Commission by Professor 
 Lauck and Mr. Sydenstricker. The data contained in these 
 reports were perused by them in a book published in 19 17.* 
 This is what they actually have to say on the subject: 
 
 The recent advances in wage rates which have been occasioned by 
 the unusual demand for labor at a time of restricted immigration con- 
 stitute, of course, a certain advantage in economic status to wage earn- 
 ers in many instances. . . . How far these increases in rates, aside from 
 the increases in earnings made possible by steady employment during 
 a period of great industrial activity, have kept pace with increases in 
 prices of necessaries and of the ordinary comforts used by wage-earning 
 families, is impossible of statement until accurate statistics are ob- 
 tained and published. 8 
 
 A vast amount of statistical data on every aspect of the 
 economic situation has since been published. A brief sum- 
 mary of t'he available evidence will be sufficient to disprove 
 the optimistic assurance of the Industrial Commission. 
 
 At the annual meetings of the American Economic and 
 the American Statistical Association held at Atlantic City 
 in December, 1920, two series of index numbers of physical 
 production were presented, one by Dr. Walter W. Stewart, 
 the other by Dr. Edmund E. Day. Though their indices 
 differ for particular years, yet both show a growth of pro- 
 duction during the war period much in excess of the rate of 
 the preceding quadrennial period. 
 
 A comparative summary of the principal items of both 
 series for the years 1910, 1914, and 1918 is presented in 
 Table 133 next following, where the index numbers are con- 
 
 1 Industrial Relations: Final Report and Testimony, vol. i, p. 144. 
 s W. Jett Lauck and Edgar Sydenstricker: Condition of Labor in 
 American Industries, p. xi. 
 9 Ibid., pp. 70-71. 
 
The Lessons of the War 
 
 495 
 
 verted to the base of 1914 as 100. The comparative growth 
 of manufactures, mining, agriculture, and population, during 
 the war and the preceding period beginning with 1899, is 
 shown graphically in Diagram XXIX, reproduced from Doc- 
 tor Day's Chart A. 
 
 TABLE 133 
 
 INDICES OF MANUFACTURES, MINING, AND TRANSPORTATION, IQIO, 
 1914, 
 
 
 Manufactures 
 
 Mining 
 
 
 Year 
 
 
 
 TVAnJTV>rfr at inn 
 
 
 Day's 
 
 Stewart's 
 
 Day's 
 
 Stewart's 
 
 
 1910. . . . 
 
 97 
 
 9 8 
 
 IOO 
 
 94 
 
 96 
 
 1914.... 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 IOO 
 
 1918 
 
 125 
 
 144 
 
 138 
 
 132 
 
 139 
 
 This unparalleled growth of industry was marked by ex- 
 traordinary profits. The following analysis is quoted from 
 a survey presented to the United States Railroad Labor 
 Board by Prof. W. Jett Lauck, on behalf of a number of 
 labor unions. His evidence is taken from the financial re- 
 ports of 205 large corporations, with an aggregate capital 
 stock of over $5,000,000,000. Their annual net income in- 
 creased from an average of 8.7 per cent for the pre-war 
 period 1912-1914, to an average of 23.9 per cent for the 
 war period 1916-1918. 
 
 After all expenses of operation and maintenance had been paid (says 
 Professor Lauck), after all charges for replacement of capital had been 
 set aside in fact, after every conceivable or imaginary expense had 
 been met these great groups of corporations, controlling the various 
 products essential to our life, made profits which were sufficient to re- 
 place the entire value of the capital stock within a period of slightly 
 over four years. This is proved by their own published reports. 
 
 l , "An Index Number of Production," by Walter W. Stewart. Amer- 
 ican Economic Review, March, 1921, p. 68. "The Measurement of 
 Variations in the National Real Income," by Edmund E. Day. Quar- 
 terly of the American Statistical Association, March, 1921, p. 555. 
 
496 
 
 300 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 DIAGRAM XXIX. 
 
 200 
 
 1099 
 
 1905 
 
 1910 
 
 1915 
 
 1919 
 
 XXIX. Indices of Physical Production for Agriculture, Mining and 
 Manufacture, 1899-1919. 
 
 Those corporations were not at all exceptional. The ex- 
 traordinary profits of industry during the war appear in a 
 document submitted to the Senate by the Treasury Depart- 
 ment, entitled "Corporate Earnings and Government Rev- 
 enue." This document shows the incomes of approximately 
 20,000 corporations. Altogether they earned in 1917 an 
 average return on capital stock of 33.5 per cent, after all 
 taxes had been deducted. 
 
 Over one-fourth of these corporations, 5,724 in number, showed net 
 profits of over 50 per cent on capital stock. And over one-tenth of them 
 (2,030) showed net profits of over 100 per cent. In other words, there 
 were over 5,000 corporations which, in 1917, earned over one-half the 
 value of their capital stock and over 2,000 that earned the entire value 
 in a single year. 1 
 
 1 W. Jett Lauck: The Relation Between Wages and the Increased Cost 
 of Living, pp. 7, 9-12. 
 
The Lessons of the War 497 
 
 The preceding analysis was made by a representative of 
 organized labor. The same conclusions, however, are reached 
 by Professor Friday, who, in his study of the relations between 
 profits, wages, and prices, endeavors to take a judicial atti- 
 tude, although inclining at times toward the capital side. 
 The net income of all corporations, as reported to the Bureau 
 of Internal Revenue, amounted in 1914 approximately to 
 $3,700,000,000; in 1916 it more than doubled, reaching well 
 nigh $8,600,000,000. When the United States entered the 
 war, the corporations were made to yield to the government 
 in excess profit taxes about $2,000,000,000, and yet their 
 profits for the year 1917 remained at the level of the pre- 
 vious year. Of course the net earnings of the various classes 
 of corporations widely varied. The earnings of mining and 
 manufacturing corporations in 1917 were nearly 330 per cent 
 of those of 1913, the largest pre-war year. A classification 
 of manufacturing, mining, and mercantile corporations ac- 
 cording to the percentage ratio of their net income to in- 
 vested capital shows that more than one-half of the total 
 net income was earned by concerns which made 30 per cent 
 or over. The profits of railroads and other public utility 
 corporations, being regulated by the public authorities, did 
 not rise to such heights, yet in 1916 they were 53 per cent 
 above the 1913 level, and in 1917 they still remained 30 per 
 cent above the pre-war level. "The popular impression," 
 sums up Professor Friday, "that the war has brought a large 
 increase in profits is fully borne out by the facts. The 
 growth has been large, even after the payment of income and 
 excess profits taxes." 1 
 
 A glance at Diagram XXIX will show how far the growth 
 of population lagged behind the industrial expansion of the 
 war years. This was directly due to the decrease of immi- 
 gration. The annual net immigration or emigration of bread- 
 winners from July i, 1914, to June 30, 1919, is shown in 
 Table 134. 
 
 1 David Friday: Profits, Wages, and Prices, pp. 14, 15, 18, 36, 38, 39. 
 
498 Immigration and Labor 
 
 TABLE 134. 
 
 NET IMMIGRATION OR EMIGRATION OF BREADWINNERS, 
 
 Year ended Net immigration (+) 
 
 June 30th or emigration (-) 
 
 1915 
 
 1916 
 
 1917 
 
 1918 
 
 1919 
 
 Total +138,149 
 
 The excess of all alien arrivals over all departing aliens, in- 
 cluding dependents ("persons without occupation, mostly 
 women and children," in official terminology) aggregated 
 during the same period 431,884. Thus, the additions to the 
 population through immigration during the war period rep- 
 resented mostly dependents of immigrants who had previously 
 settled in the United States. The addition of 138,149 immi- 
 grant breadwinners was by far insufficient to make up for the 
 mortality among earlier immigrants. 2 
 
 The effects of the cessation of immigration upon the state 
 of the labor market are reflected in the statistics compiled 
 by the New York State Industrial Commission. From the 
 month of March, 1916, to the end of the year 1918, the sup- 
 ply of labor registered at the public employment offices 
 varied from 97.1 per cent to 47.1 per cent of the demand for 
 labor. 3 
 
 Such was the relation of supply and demand at the gate- 
 way of the United States. That this condition was not 
 exceptional, is evidenced by the suspension of the contract- 
 labor law in 1917, 1918, 1919, and 1920, in order to enable 
 
 1 See Appendix, Table XXXI. 
 
 2 During the ten years from July I, 1910, to June 30, 1920, the excess 
 of arriving over departing aliens aggregated 3,123,000 persons (see Ap- 
 pendix, Table XXX.). The increase of the foreign-born population 
 from the XIII. to the XIV. Census (1910-1920) was only 358,000 (see 
 Table 7 on p. 88). The decrease of the number of foreign-born by 
 death thus amounted to 2,765,000. 
 
 8 See Appendix, Table XXXII. 
 
The Lessons of the War 499 
 
 mine operators and other employers in the Southwest to 
 import Mexican laborers under contract. 1 During those 
 four years 50,800 Mexican contract laborers were imported 
 under departmental regulations which were tantamount to 
 peonage. 2 This measure is justified, in a report of a com- 
 mittee appointed by Ex-Secretary of Labor Wilson, by "the 
 fact that immigration from Europe had practically ceased." 
 It is explained that "a dire and imperative need was met in 
 making the exceptions and permitting Mexican labor to enter 
 this country on easy terms to meet the abnormal demand for 
 common labor." It should be remembered that Mr. Wilson 
 was made the first Secretary of Labor as the spokesman for 
 organized labor, having been a vice-president of the Amer- 
 ican Federation of Labor and a district president of the 
 United Mine Workers. Obviously such a striking departure 
 from the policy of organized labor must have been necessi- 
 tated by a genuine scarcity of labor. 8 
 
 The effects of the war upon the state of the labor market 
 during the war are well summarized in the following excerpt 
 from a recent book on war-time strikes: 
 
 In times of emergency and consequent abnormal labor demand, there 
 arises a competition for men which disturbs to a marked degree the wage 
 relationships of normal times. For normal times, as our economic 
 system is constituted, have always meant times of labor surplus. . . . 
 When, however, the demand for men far exceeds the supply, employers 
 compete among one another and are willing in many cases to pay 
 wages even higher than union rates. In open-shop industries men were 
 offered these increased rates irrespective of their union membership. 
 ... A further consequence of the abnormal war conditions was an un- 
 precedented mobility of labor. Every method, including patriotic ap- 
 peals in the press and on public platforms, was used to bring home to 
 the workers of other localities the need of men in places where war 
 
 1 Monthly Labor Review, November, 1920, p. 223. 
 
 2 See note in the Appendix. 
 
 8 Still, the same Secretary Wilson, in a press statement under date of 
 January 10, 1918, said that there was "an ample supply of labor both 
 for the army and for industry." (The Evening Telegram, New York, 
 January 13, 1918.) Apparently, however, such official pronouncements 
 must be taken with a grain of salt. 
 
500 Immigration and Labor 
 
 material was being produced. Influenced both by the patriotic motive 
 and the desire for better wages, men and women left their homes and 
 traveled to distant cities. This movement of the workers was acceler- 
 ated by the action of employers who, not content with elaborate news- 
 paper advertisements offering high rates of wages, even went as far 
 as to send labor scouts all over the country. Both of these practices 
 had to be curtailed by the government when toward the end of the 
 war the competition for men became fiercer than ever and the U. S. 
 Employment Service was organized in an effort to control the situation. 
 . . . Workers not only left their homes but they changed from one in- 
 dustry to another with a freedom never before known. General wage 
 levels were a matter of common knowledge. And the worker knew not 
 only the pay of men in his own industry but also that of workers in many 
 other trades. 1 
 
 According to scholastic theory, "with employers com- 
 peting more eagerly to get workmen, with the better em- 
 ployers ready to pay appreciably higher wages than before, 
 with resident laborers not subject to fresh competition from 
 abroad, the time is ripe for a real increase of wages." 2 Did 
 this ideal combination of economic factors during the late 
 war actually produce the "salutary effects" anticipated by 
 the Commission on Industrial Relations? 
 
 Applying the standard chosen by the Commission, viz., the 
 rise of the wage scale apace with food prices, we find that the 
 purchasing power of union wages considerably declined dur- 
 ing the war, as shown in Table 135. 
 
 A painstaking study of the movement of real wages gauged 
 by retail prices of food has been made by Professor Douglas 
 
 1 Alexander M. Bing, War-time Strikes, pp. 196-197. According to a 
 special study of mobility of labor made by the United States Bureau of 
 Labor Statistics for the decade 1910-1919, "each year, on the average, 
 the number of persons who quit, who were laid off or were discharged, 
 as well as the number who had to be hired, was much larger than the 
 total number of workers on the force at any one time." During the 
 period from the entrance of the United States into the war, to the armis- 
 tice (i.e., from May, 1917, to October, 1918), the monthly mobility rates 
 were far above the average. ' ' Mobility of Labor in American Industry, ' ' 
 by Paul F. Brissenden and Emil Frankel: Monthly Labor Review, June, 
 1920, pp. 41-43. 
 
 "Hourwich's Immigration and Labor," by Robert F. Foerster: The 
 Quarterly Journal of Economics, August, 1913, p. 668. 
 
The Lessons of the War 501 
 
 TABLE 135. 
 
 PURCHASING POWER OF UNION WAGE RATES, MEASURED BY RETAIL 
 PRICES OF FOOD, 1913-19! 8. 1 
 
 Year Per hour Per week 
 
 1913 100 100 
 
 1914 ioo 99 
 
 1915 101 101 
 
 1916 94 93 
 
 1917 78 77 
 
 1918 79 77 
 
 and Miss Lamberson. They have arrived at the following 
 conclusions concerning the effects of the war upon the con- 
 dition of the American wage worker: 
 
 All the evidence seems to indicate that at the termination of the 
 great war the return in commodities which the American workman 
 received for an equal length of time worked (one hour) was from 7 to 
 17 per cent less than it was before the sharp, upward movement of 
 prices in 1916. The purchasing power of the established week's work, 
 moreover, was from 10 to 20 per cent less than in 1915. American labor, 
 as a whole, therefore, cannot legitimately be charged with having prof- 
 iteered during the war. Rather, like Alice in Wonderland, it was 
 compelled to run faster in order to stay in the same place. 2 
 
 The material for these conclusions was taken from the 
 wage statistics of ten leading industries. The authors, there- 
 fore, caution the reader against generalization from their re- 
 sults without certain reservations, of which the following are 
 the most important : 
 
 1 Monthly Labor Review, March, 1919, p. 120. The United States 
 Bureau of Labor Statistics has expressed the view that union rates of 
 wages are merely minimum rates and that in practice union workers 
 earn more than that minimum. Other students, however, take the 
 opposite view. "The union rates of pay are the so-called minimum 
 rates. As a matter of experience, however, these minimum rates are 
 usually the prevailing rates." Hugh S. Hanna and W. Jett Lauck: 
 Wages and War, p. 2. This view is concurred in by Mr. Bing, an em- 
 ployer of labor, of large business experience, who served the govern- 
 ment during the war. Bing, loc. tit., p. 196. 
 
 2 "The Movement of Real Wages," by Paul H. Douglas and Frances 
 Lamberson : The A merican Economic Review, September, 1 92 1 , pp. 425- 
 426. 
 
502 Immigration and Labor 
 
 The industries covered do not include such war-time industries as 
 munitions plants. Some of the occupations within these industries 
 enjoyed increases in wages more than sufficient to compensate for the 
 increase in the cost of living. On the other hand, neither are the rail- 
 road workers and the coal miners included, and their wages notoriously 
 lagged behind the increase in prices. Farm laborers also lost during the 
 war period. 1 
 
 Still, in recent studies of the United States Bureau of Labor 
 Statistics, and in the compilations of the National Industrial 
 Conference Board, retail prices of food alone have been con- 
 sidered unsatisfactory as a measure of the cost of living, 
 inasmuch as they do not reflect the changes in other items of 
 the family budget, notably rent. 2 The adequacy of other 
 standards, however, has likewise been questioned. 3 Profes- 
 sor Litman, in his study of prices during the war, comes to 
 the following conclusions: 
 
 As to any definite conclusions regarding increased cost of living and 
 the effect of this increase upon the status of the workingman and his 
 family, one may subscribe without reservation to the statements of 
 
 1 "The Movement of Real Wages,'' by Paul H. Douglas and Frances 
 Lamberson: The American Economic Review, September, 1921, pp. 421- 
 422. 
 
 According to the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics, the 
 average cost of housing for thirty-two cities showed practically no change 
 from 1913 to the end of 1917; in December, 1918, it increased 9.2 per 
 cent from the 1913 average. The increase in rents came as the after- 
 math of the war. Monthly Labor Review, July, 1921, p. 112. 
 
 * "At the present time, index numbers of the cost of living, like all 
 other index numbers, are still in the experimental stage of development. 
 They cannot yet be considered instruments of precision like thermome- 
 ters or micrometer calipers. And no one is at this time justified in sit- 
 ting with an eye peeled on the index number of the cost of living and 
 measuring its movement in one direction or another, and believing that 
 whatever the index registers is above question or criticism. For retail 
 price quotations of standardized goods and services are not easy to 
 collect, and when one index number is compared with another, small 
 but not unimportant discrepancies frequently appear. . . . They are 
 due to differences in the manner of collecting price quotations, in the 
 instructions to enumerators, in the training and judgment of the 
 enumerators, and in the kinds of goods and services that are included in 
 the survey by each agency." Leo Wolman: "The Cost of Living and 
 Wage Cuts," The New Republic, July 27, 1921. 
 
The Lessons of the War 503 
 
 the United States Commissioner of Labor Statistics, that after all these 
 years of investigation and statistical toil in the cost-of-living field, we 
 don't know clearly the difference between the higher cost of living and 
 the cost of higher living. 1 
 
 Yet, after a careful examination of all available data, Pro- 
 fessor Litman cautiously concludes that "it does not seem 
 that wages rose as rapidly as the prices of commodities. 2 
 
 This view is concurred in by those who speak for organized 
 labor. The following is from Prof. Lauck's statement be- 
 fore the United States Railroad Labor Board, quoted on a 
 previous page: 
 
 An examination of the experience of every industry shows, practi- 
 cally without exception, that wage increases have lagged behind price 
 increases, and usually very far behind. . . . They [the workers] have 
 merely struggled as best they could and in the only way they could to 
 keep their old standards of living. In this struggle they have met with 
 only very partial success. For the great body of wage earners, wages 
 have not kept step with prices. As a result, labor as a class is now 
 worse off than it was before the war. Almost without exception a 
 day's wage buys less than it did in 1912 to 1914. In other words, in 
 the distribution of the income of the country, labor is receiving a 
 smaller proportion than it did before the war, while capital in the form 
 of profits, interest, and rent is receiving a very much larger pro- 
 portion. 3 
 
 On the other hand, the same statistical material leads Pro- 
 fessor Friday to the opposite conclusion, viz., "that the real 
 wages of labor have risen, and are higher to-day than they 
 were in 1914." 4 But at the end of the same chapter, he 
 qualifies this general statement as follows: 
 
 There are so many different kinds of labor, so many different kinds of 
 wage payment, and so many different rates of pay, that the task of 
 obtaining a general view of the course of wages is considered by experts 
 to be one of the most difficult and complicated scientific undertakings 
 
 1 Simon Litman: Prices and Price Control in Great Britain and the 
 United States During the World War, p. 201. 
 
 2 Ibid., p. 197. 
 
 3 Loc. cit., p. 5. 
 
 * Friday: Profits, Wages, and Prices, p. 107. 
 
504 Immigration and Labor 
 
 in the whole field of economics Consequently all general statementa 
 
 regarding wages, of which many are always appearing in print and on 
 the platform, should be accepted with extreme caution. 1 
 
 His own computation of the increase in wage rates and 
 employment of from ten to twelve million workers shows 
 that the yearly earnings per employee increased from 1913 
 to 1917 slightly over 30 per cent, 2 whereas it appears from 
 other sources that the cost of living during the same period 
 increased 42 per cent. 3 
 
 The most conclusive corroboration of the decline in real 
 wages is furnished by the investigations of the Bureau of 
 Child Hygiene of New York City, which show a decided in- 
 crease of the proportion of malnourished school children dur- 
 ing the World War. The figures are presented in Table 136. 
 
 TABLE 136. 
 
 PROPORTION OF MALNOURISHED SCHOOL CHILDREN IN THE BOROUGH OF 
 MANHATTAN, NEW YORK CITY. 4 
 
 Year Per cent 
 
 I9H 5 
 
 1915 6 
 
 1916 12 
 
 1917 21 
 
 This condition was not peculiar to New York City only. 
 Dr. Thomas D. Wood, in an address delivered before the 
 National Council of Education, February 28, 1918, estimated 
 "that between 15 and 25 per cent of our school children are 
 undernourished." 5 
 
 ^ Was this lagging of wages behind the advancing cost of 
 living due to the failure of the wage workers to "insist" upon 
 a higher rate of wagesto put it in the language of the eco- 
 
 1 Friday: Profits, Wages, and Prices, pp. no-ill. 
 8 Ibid., p. 122. 
 
 ' Monthly Labor Bulletin, February, 19*1, p. 61. 
 4 "What Is Malnutrition?" by Lydia Roberts. Children's Bureau, 
 Publication No. 59, p. 7. 
 1 Ibid. t pp. 7, 19. 
 
The Lessons of the War 505 
 
 nomic experts of the Immigration Commission? The statis- 
 tics of strikes during the world war prove that labor did 
 not submissively acquiesce in the terms offered to it by 
 employers. 
 
 In the period from 1881 to 1905 there occurred on an aver- 
 age 1,532 strikes a year. During the three years 1916-1918 
 the number of strikes averaged more than twice as many, 
 viz., 3,697. The annual average number of strikers during 
 the decade, preceding the predominance of the "new immi- 
 gration" was 267,000, and in the first decade of its ascend- 
 ancy 344, ooo. 1 During the years 1916-1918, the annual 
 average number of strikers rose to i,3io,ooo, 2 i.e., 391 per 
 cent above the average of 1886-1895, whereas the num- 
 ber of persons engaged in manufacturing and mechanical 
 pursuits, trade, and transportation, increased from the X. 
 to the XIII. Census (1880-1910) only 208 per cent. 3 Nor 
 were those strikes unorganized outbursts of inarticulate dis- 
 content. The percentage of strikes in which the workers 
 were members of unions rose from 82 in 1915 to 90 in 1917, 
 and remained at 83 in 1918. 4 
 
 Moreover, strikes were not the only means by which labor 
 was able to assert its claims: 
 
 During the war the principle of collective bargaining was of necessity, 
 albeit in many cases rather grudgingly, recognized by all employers 
 engaged on direct government work or in the production of essentials. 
 The Quartermaster Corps, the Ordnance Office, the Emergency Fleet 
 Corporation of the Shipping Board, the National War Labor Board, 
 the Fuel Administration, and many other government agencies, sought 
 to secure greater and more continuous production by means of collective 
 agreements covering wages. 5 
 
 1 See Table 104, on p. 345. 
 
 2 Alexander M. Bing: War-time Strikes, pp. 292-293. 
 
 3 XIII. Census Reports, vol. iv, p. 41. 
 * Bing, loc. cit., p. 297. 
 
 5 Royal Meeker, Commissioner of Labor Statistics: "Employees 
 Representation in Management of Industry," Monthly Labor Review, 
 February, 1920, p. 2. 
 
506 
 
 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Neither could the presence of the "un-Americanized" for- 
 eign worker serve as an explanation for the decline of real 
 wages. It has been brought out, on the basis of the calcula- 
 tions of the Bureau of Applied Economics, that whereas the 
 real wages of common laborers in the iron and steel industry 
 of whom 64 per cent are foreign born have gone up, those of 
 locomotive firemen of whom 84 per cent are native-born 
 Americans have declined to a point 31 per cent below "the 
 minimum budget under American standards." 1 
 
 Among the potent factors in the decline of real wages 
 must be noted the movement of labor from agriculture to 
 urban industries in response to the attraction of higher 
 wages. In consequence, agricultural production during the 
 war barely kept pace with the growth of population, 2 while 
 the demand for breadstuff s was increased by exports abroad, 
 as indicated in Table 137. The great interests which control 
 
 TABLE 137. 
 
 WHEAT PRODUCED, EXPORTED, AND RETAINED FOR CONSUMPTION, FISCAL 
 YEARS I9II-I9I8. 3 
 
 Millions of bushels 
 
 Years end< 
 
 ;d June 30 
 
 Increase (+) 
 or decrease ( ) 
 
 
 1911-1914 
 
 1915-1918 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Produced l 
 
 2 7 en 
 
 3IQO 
 
 -1- 16 
 
 Exported, domestic 2 
 
 4,-ie 
 
 OI "? 
 
 -j-IIQ 
 
 Domestic, retained for consumption. . . 
 
 2,315 
 
 2,275 
 
 2 
 
 Per cent exported 
 
 16 
 
 2O 
 
 
 
 
 * 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 The production is of the calendar year preceding the fiscal year 
 1 including wheat flour reduced to wheat. 
 
 the agricultural produce market were thereby enabled to 
 raise the prices of food. What the wage earner gained in 
 
 1 Editorial in The New Republic, February 25, 1920, p. 373. XIII. 
 Census Reports, vol. iv, Table VI: Laborers in blast furnaces and steel 
 rolling mills, iron foundries, and other iron and steel factories; loco- 
 motive firemen (computed). 
 
 9 See Diagram XXIX. 
 
 8 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1918, p. 559. For statistics 
 of exports of other breadstuffs, see Appendix, Table XXXIII. 
 
The Lessons of the War 507 
 
 money wages, he was forced to surrender in the higher prices 
 of necessities of life. This fact is established by Prof. Wesley 
 C. Mitchell's study of prices during the war, from which 
 Table 138 is compiled. 
 
 TABLE 138. 
 
 INDEX NUMBERS OF THE YEARLY PRODUCTION AND PRICES OF VEGETABLE 
 PRODUCTS, 1913-1918. l 
 
 Years Production Prices] 
 
 1913 100 100 
 
 1914 106 95 
 
 1915 112 98 
 
 1916 100 in 
 
 1917 107 173 
 
 1918 106 191 
 
 The next question to be considered is, What were the sub- 
 stitutes for immigrant labor during the war years? The 
 movement of workers from agriculture to urban industries 
 has already been referred to. It struck the public eye in 
 the migration of Negroes from the agricultural South to the 
 industrial East and Middle West. The volume of that 
 migration is officially estimated at from 400,000 to 500,000. 
 "Shortage of labor in Northern industries" is given as "the 
 direct cause of the increased Negro migration during the war 
 period." "The agricultural regions of the Southern states 
 began to suffer for want of the Negro worker." 2 
 
 1 "History of Prices During the War," by Wesley C. Mitchell: W. I. 
 B. Price Bulletin No. I, p. 45. "In vegetable husbandry the harvest 
 depends partly upon the acreage sown, which the farmer can control, 
 but quite as much upon the weather. Thus the annual supply of veg- 
 etable products increased in the dull year 1914 and increased largely 
 again in 1915. Nineteen sixteen was a bad year, and all the efforts to 
 encourage agriculture in 1917 and 1918 did not bring the harvests close 
 to the 1915 record." (Ibid., p. 46.) 
 
 2 ' ' The Negro at Work During the World War ' ' : Department of Labor 
 Division of Negro Economics, George E. Haynes, Director. Second 
 Study on Negro Labor, p. 10. See also: Emmett J. Scott: Negro Mi- 
 gration During the War, pp. 3, 14. According to a preliminary state- 
 ment issued by the Bureau of the Census, the Negro population of 
 Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, Mississippi, and Louisiana decreased 
 from 1910 to 1920 by 142,598. On the other hand, of the total numerical 
 increase in the Negro population of the United States during that de- 
 
508 Immigration and Labor 
 
 Another substitute for immigrant labor was found in the 
 employment of women. The statistics on the subject are 
 scattered in government publications. An illustration is fur- 
 nished by the Annual Report of the Director-General of Rail- 
 roads for 1919, from which we learn that in October, 1918, 
 the number of women employed on tbe railroads had in- 
 creased, from the entrance of the United States into the war, 
 by about 70,000, which represented an addition of 225 per 
 cent. 1 
 
 The increased employment of children in industry during 
 the war emergency was still another substitute for immigrant 
 labor. The subject is dealt with in a report of the Children's 
 Bureau, from which the following is condensed : 
 
 By the latter part of 1915 the effect of foreign orders for war goods 
 was beginning to make itself felt in the increased employment of chil- 
 dren. Beginning with the autumn of 1915 an unprecedented rise began 
 in the number of children entering gainful employment, and heavy in- 
 creases were practically everywhere recorded for 1916 and 1917, even 
 before the United States entered the war. After the entrance of the 
 United States into the war the number of children taking out employ- 
 ment certificates continued to rise. The forces at work pushing chil- 
 dren into industry included the growing cost of the necessities of life com- 
 bined, in many cases, with the absence on military duty of members of 
 the family who had previously contributed to its support. High wages 
 offered by employers hard pressed for help proved a powerful magnet, 
 drawing into business and industry many children under sixteen who 
 in normal times would have remained in school. In several cities the 
 increase in 1918 was so striking as to arrest attention even in that year 
 of generally large increases. In Washington, D. C., there was an in- 
 crease of more than 163 per cent in 1917-18 (July 1st to June 3Oth) 
 over 1916-17. In Louisville, Kentucky, there was an increase in 1918 
 of 52 per cent, following an increase in 1917 of 174 per cent, so that the 
 
 cade, 69 per cent took place in the North, although its Negro popula- 
 tion in 1920 was only 14 per cent of the total for the United States. 
 In several of the Northern states the rates were extraordinarily large, 
 e.g., in Pennsylvania, 46.7 per cent; in Ohio, 67.1 per cent; in Michi- 
 gan, 251 per cent; in Illinois, 67.1 per cent. 
 1 Monthly Labor Review. March, 1920, p. 156 
 
The Lessons of the War 509 
 
 number of children receiving employment certificates was in 1918 over 
 four times as great as in 1916. In Philadelphia an increase of 82 per 
 cent in 1917 was followed by a still further increase of 15 per cent in 
 1918. It should be kept in mind that the figures here given relate only 
 to children legally certificated, and give no indication of the numbers 
 going to work without complying with the law. Reports from labor 
 commissioners and factory inspectors indicated the difficulty experi- 
 enced during the war years in adequately administering child-labor 
 laws. Parents and children, tempted by the high wages offered the 
 children at a time when the excessive cost of living presented a serious 
 problem, would connive at evasions of the law in order to have the chil- 
 dren work in factories and munitions plants. In Philadelphia violations 
 of the child-labor law were four times as great in 1917 as in 1916. In 
 inspections made by the Children's Bureau of sixty-three shipyards 
 where steel ships were being built, approximately 60 per cent of the 
 children found at work who claimed to be sixteen and were without 
 certificates were actually only fourteen or fifteen years of age. The 
 reply of the Assistant Secretary of the Industrial Commission of Wis- 
 consin to an inquiry sent out in 1918 by the Children's Bureau in regard 
 to this subject pointed out the fact that "The general effect of the war 
 upon the enforcement of the child-labor law has been to increase the 
 difficulty of enforcing the law. The scarcity of adult labor has made 
 the employer more ready to take minors into his employ. Many em- 
 ployers now employ children who have never done so before to any 
 extent." x 
 
 What is the lesson that can be drawn from the experience 
 gained in the late war? Amidst the present industrial crisis 
 one must not lose sight of the fact that this is but one of the 
 cyclical disturbances of the capitalistic system which will be 
 followed by resumption of "business as usual." There will 
 be profits which will seek investment in new fields. Prior to 
 the war most of that surplus was applied to the expansion of 
 American industry, which created a demand for immigrant 
 labor. If restriction of immigration is to become the per- 
 manent policy of the United States, our recent war experience 
 does not warrant the assumption that the resulting scarcity 
 of labor will inure to the benefit of the American wage worker. 
 
 1 "Trend of Child Labor in the United States, 1913-1920," by Nettie 
 McGill. Monthly Labor Review, April, 1921, pp. 6-10. 
 
Immigration and Labor 
 
 It seems likely that the restriction of immigration of labor 
 from Europe will lead to emigration of American capital to 
 
 Europe. 
 
 That this is not mere speculation, appears from an official 
 report of the Commercial Secretary of the British Embassy 
 in Berlin, who states that arrangements have been in progress 
 between American capitalists and German corporations, look- 
 ing toward the investment of American capital in German 
 industry. The electrical and textile industries and shipping 
 are mentioned. 1 
 
 The decline of real wages during the late war is merely a 
 repetition of the story of the Civil War; the cause of it has 
 been stated in a previous chapter. 2 The bargaining power 
 of the wage earner does not extend to the market in which 
 he appears as a consumer. Advances in wages come as a 
 result of the slow process of collective bargaining, involving 
 the use of the cumbersome machinery of arbitration, with 
 occasional resort to industrial warfare, whereas the prices of 
 commodities consumed by the wage earner are controlled by 
 monopolistic combinations, which promptly add every ad- 
 
 1 General Report on the Industrial and Economic Situation in Germany 
 in December, 1920, p. 6. Presented to Parliament by Command of His 
 Majesty. London, 1921. In a press dispatch cabled from Paris under 
 date of September n, 1921, it was reported that an agreement was 
 signed between representatives of a big American syndicate and the 
 Archduke Frederick of Austria and his family, by which the syndicate 
 took over the whole of the Archduke's estates in the dismembered 
 Austrian Empire. These estates include the rich steel works and mines 
 at Teschen, vast forest lands stretching across many miles of several 
 new Central European republics, farms, factories, etc. The value of 
 the property is conservatively estimated at $200,000,000. In the syn- 
 dicate which is taking the control of this property are mentioned names 
 prominent in American financial circles. The negotiations began in 
 the summer of 1919. An arrangement was made in October, 1919, 
 whereby the Archduke was to transfer his various properties and in- 
 terests to a corporation which was then organized in Switzerland. The 
 deal involves litigation in the courts of the new republics, and ex- 
 premier Viviani of France is reported to have been retained as counsel 
 to represent the claims of the Austrian Archduke before the League of 
 Nations. 
 
 * See p. 306. 
 
The Lessons of the War 511 
 
 vance in wages to the market price of the finished product. 1 
 Thus the raise of wages of one group of workers is in effect 
 charged up to the working class as a whole. 
 
 The leak is in the control of prices. The government, dur- 
 ing the war, assumed the authority to regulate prices, but it 
 delegated this authority to representatives of the interests 
 which were to be regulated. 2 The profiteering which resulted 
 from the methods of price control adopted by the various 
 war agencies, was exposed in a report submitted by the 
 Federal Trade Commission to the Senate in the summer of 
 1918. The profits assured to the big interests were "enor- 
 mous ... far beyond anything that was necessary to keep 
 men in industry and to stimulate their initiative and enter- 
 prise." 3 What is wanted in order to secure to the worker a 
 real advance in wages, is regulation of profits in the interest 
 of the consumers, of whom the wage earners constitute the 
 most numerous single group. 
 
 Restriction of the supply of labor does not touch the prob- 
 lem of price control. Immigration laws can prevent the 
 American capitalist from employing foreign labor in the 
 United States. But with the present rates of exchange he 
 may find it as profitable to employ the same labor in Europe 
 in the manufacture of goods for the world market. The re- 
 duction of the supply of labor will be met by a reduction of 
 the demand for labor. Restriction of immigration will merely 
 speed the advance of financial imperialism. 
 
 1 "Wage earners, as soon as they could make their economic demands 
 felt, thereupon received wage increases so that they might in a measure 
 cope with the advance in the cost of living. This meant increased labor 
 costs to the producers and middlemen, and they instantly advanced 
 prices again. Almost without exception, these price advances were out 
 of all proportion to the increase in labor costs. This necessitated further 
 wage increases to labor, and we find the vicious circle established, with 
 the profiteers invariably in command of the situation." "Profiteers," 
 by W. Jett Lauck: The Socialist Review, July, 1920, p. 52. 
 
 1 "Most of the important positions in the Food Administration were 
 entrusted to successful organizers and administrators of private busi- 
 ness enterprises." Litman: loc. cit., p. 211. 
 
 * Friday: loc. cit., p. 155. 
 
Appendix 
 
IN ANSWER TO CRITICS 1 
 
 THE first edition of this book was attacked by two authors 
 of books on immigration. This record of the critics calls 
 for an examination of their objections. 
 
 Prof. Fairchild goes at it with the habits acquired in mark- 
 ing examination papers. It could not escape his trained eye 
 that the name of Prof. Willcox was misspelled (with one "1" 
 instead of two). The error is repentantly admitted, and has 
 been corrected in the present edition. He is less fortunate, 
 however, in other attempts of a similar kind. Thus he finds 
 fault with the remark in the footnote on p. 60 that the con- 
 clusion of the Immigration Commission that "'the employ- 
 ment of the wife, or keeping boarders or lodgers, is less fre- 
 quent among the native-born of foreign father' ... is de- 
 rived from the reports in just four families, whose heads 
 are native-born of foreign father." He has taken the pains 
 to look up the reference, and announces to have found that 
 there were 26 such families instead of 4. Examination of 
 Table 44, on p. 310 of the volume quoted shows, however, 
 in the column headed "number of wives having employment 
 or keeping boarders or lodgers," exactly 4 such wives. As 
 there is, presumably, one wife to each family, this is equiva- 
 lent to four families. The critic has evidently been misled 
 by the figure 26, which is shown in another column headed 
 "number of selected families," for the "total native-born of 
 selected families." 
 
 This desire to pick flaws reaches a climax on p. 762 of 
 Prof. Fairchild's review. In Table 8 the author has copied 
 from the Reports of the Immigration Commission, the sta- 
 
 1 Henry Pratt Fairchild, in The National Municipal Review, vol. ii, 
 (1913)- Robert F. Foerster, in The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 
 August, 1913. 
 
Appendix 
 
 tistics of the movement of third-class passengers between 
 the United States and European ports during the calendar 
 years 1899-1909. The number of west-bound passengers is 
 reported to have fallen from 1,378,000 in 1907, to 420,000 in 
 1908, which shows a decline of 058,000-, the net immigration, 
 i.e., the excess of east-bound over west-bound passengers for 
 the year 1908, is 237,000. These figures are commented 
 upon by the author as follows : 
 
 During the industrial crisis of 1908, immigration dropped at once 
 nearly a million, compared with the high-water mark of the previous 
 year. . . . The result was a net loss of nearly a quarter of a million through 
 emigration (p. 92). 
 
 Prof. Fairchild has not troubled himself to look at Table 8, 
 instead of which he has made a computation of his own from 
 some other source he does not take the reader into his 
 secret and has obtained the figures 859,642 and 41,198, re- 
 spectively, instead of those commented upon by the author. 
 On this ground the author is charged with "intent to mis- 
 lead." The American academic world prides itself upon its 
 "catholicity": there are two sides to every question, etc. 
 But, when met by heterodox opinion, the priest of the Tem- 
 ple of Wisdom loses his scholarly poise and falls into the ways 
 of the vulgus profanum. 
 
 Concerning the merits of the criticisms, it must be noted 
 that both reviewers reject the statistical method of treat- 
 ment of the subject of immigration. Prof. Fairchild exhorts 
 against "the besetting sin of the professional statistician, the 
 assumption that nothing is true which cannot be proved by 
 statistics" (p. 763). He is seconded by Dr. Foerster, who 
 believes that "we must go heavily armed with hypotheses. 
 . . . For to-day [he says] guarded deductive reasoning is in- 
 dispensable, and often by appropriate tests is found valid" 
 (pp. 670, 671). 
 
 It will be remembered that a Commission was appointed 
 by Congress to investigate the immigration question, and 
 
Appendix 517 
 
 that after nearly three years of study the Commission brought 
 out a report recommending restriction of immigration, in 
 support of which it presented many volumes of statistical 
 material. This evidence is ruled out by the learned econo- 
 mists, who prefer to go back to deductive reasoning and 
 hypotheses. Is it because they realize that the truth of the 
 conclusions of the Commission "cannot be proved by sta- 
 tistics ' ' ? Still, since other university professors who directed 
 its investigations tried to prove the case for restriction of 
 immigration by statistical evidence, it was incumbent upon 
 the negative side to show that their statistics had failed to 
 establish the truth of their contentions. 
 
 Let us consider, however, whether deductive reasoning 
 would do better than the inductive method. The prerequisite 
 for the application of the deductive method is the existence 
 of axioms and postulates based upon common observation 
 of facts. In pure mathematics these facts are few and sim- 
 ple, and are within the daily experience of every person. 
 Economic science, on the contrary, deals with a great num- 
 ber of complex phenomena which are not within the knowl- 
 edge of everybody. The so-called deductive Political Econ- 
 omy is in reality also based upon observed facts, but the 
 field of observation is confined to the narrow environment of 
 the scholar. A pertinent illustration is the theory of wages 
 to which both reviewers swear allegiance, viz., that the de- 
 mand for labor at periods of shortage of labor "must of 
 necessity have raised the wages of laborers already in the 
 country, if the foreign sources of supply had been cut off." l 
 The experience of labor in the late war, as well as in the Civil 
 War, has discredited this theory. Mere facts, however, have 
 no place in the speculative theory of the reviewers. 
 
 What importance can it have says Dr. Foerster to ask whether 
 wages in an immigrant occupation are higher or lower now than they 
 once were? Legislators must ask, how does unrestricted immigration 
 affect wages (p. 658). 
 
 1 Fairchild, loc. cit., p. 760. See also Foerster, loc. cit n p. 668. 
 
518 Appendix 
 
 Obviously he thinks that that question can be answered 
 by intuition, without a comparative study of the actual 
 ratfes of wages. Economists have not agreed, however, upon 
 the premises from which the legislators could readily deduce 
 an answer satisfactory to Dr. Foerster. Prof. Commons, 
 who made a study of immigration for President McKinley's 
 Industrial Commission, reached the conclusion that immi- 
 grants come in response to demand for labor, which is de- 
 pendent upon industrial expansion, and that when the ex- 
 pansion of industry is strong, "there is no overcrowding of 
 the labor market" and "the new labor as well as the existing 
 labor may secure advances in wages" (see pp. 114, 302). 
 In order to answer Dr. Foerster's hypothetical question, the 
 legislators must therefore first ascertain the following facts : 
 
 (1) Is American industry expanding fast enough to create 
 a demand for immigrant labor or, on the contrary, is there 
 an overcrowding of the labor market ? 
 
 (2) Has immigrant labor, as well as native labor, actually 
 secured advances in wages, or has immigration retarded the 
 advance of wages ? 
 
 Answers to these questions imply that very "historical 
 comparison" which is spurned by Dr. Foerster (p. 657). 
 He claims that the Immigration Commission attempted to 
 study the movement of wages in connection with immigra- 
 tion, and indulges in the following speculation: 
 
 If wages declined as immigrants entered a field and underbid the 
 workers, that would presumably prove that immigration lowers wages" 
 (p. 658). 
 
 This hypothesis merely proves that Dr. Foerster speaks 
 of the reports of the Immigration Commission without hav- 
 ing familiarized himself with them. The Commission never 
 attempted a historical study of wages, nor has it proved 
 Dr. Foerster's hypothesis. The burden of proof is obviously 
 on the restrictionist, who contends- that contemporary immi- 
 gration is responsible for low wages. The author's task has 
 been purely negative, to show the lack of evidence to support 
 
Appendix 519 
 
 the contentions of the restrictionists. How was he to go 
 about it? We are taught by Dr. Foerster that "wherever 
 wages change we must note what else characteristically 
 changes" (p. 670). In conformity with this rule, the author 
 compared the wages of immigrant and native railway men 
 for a number of years. Census statistics of wages in manu- 
 factures were compared by states in parallel columns with 
 percentages of foreign-born. If wag;es declined as immi- 
 grants entered a field, states with a large percentage of 
 immigrants would show lower average earnings than those 
 with a smaller percentage of immigrants. Likewise, the 
 movement of wages of railway employees for a period of 
 years would show a greater advance in those occupations in 
 which native Americans predominate than in those in 
 which immigrants are employed. This is, however, not the 
 case. 
 
 Both reviewers find fault with the author for making com- 
 parisons of money wages "without reference to the relative 
 cost of living." That the author is fully aware of this factor 
 the reader can see from the following sentence, appearing on 
 p. 294: "A rise or a fall in money wages is no indication of 
 an increase or decrease of the resources of the wage-earners, 
 unless coupled with comparative statistics of the cost of 
 living." But when the movement of wages is compared by 
 occupations for a number of years, the change in the cost of 
 living affects all workers alike and may, therefore, be elim- 
 inated. The defects of our statistics of the cost of living do 
 not permit of a thoroughgoing comparison of real wages 
 over different sections of the country. But, relying upon 
 Dr. Hearing's conclusion in hi's Wages in ike United States, 
 "that average wages are rather constant for\ given industry 
 from state to state," we may properly infer that the cost of 
 living must likewise vary but little from state to state. 
 From such data as are available, it does not appear that 
 immigration has had a depressing effect upon real wages. 
 In the woolen mills, "since the immigrants from southern 
 and Eastern Europe and Asiatic Turkey have begun to enter 
 
52O Appendix 
 
 the unskilled occupations in large numbers, the percentage 
 of increase in the wages of unskilled operatives has been 
 greater than the percentage of increase in the rates of skilled 
 workers, who are practically all of the English-speaking 
 races" (p. 390). Mr. Fitch, in his study of the steel workers 
 for the Pittsburgh Survey, has brought out the fact that the 
 wages of the unskilled immigrants have kept pace with the 
 cost of living, whereas the wages of the skilled native workers 
 have been reduced (see pp. 404-409). Comparisons of the 
 standard of living of the workers at different periods be- 
 ginning with 1800 show a decided improvement of the con- 
 dition of labor, going parallel with immigration (see pp. 
 295-297). This was, of course, due to the industrial progress 
 of the country, in which the workers had a share. Prof. 
 Fairchild thinks that, with the wonderful development of 
 industry in the United States, the share of the workers 
 should have been larger if it had not been for the influx of 
 immigrants. But this is begging the question. 
 
 He cites the example of Germany, where the expansion of 
 industry improved the condition of labor, and asks why it 
 has not had the same effect in the United States, the infer- 
 ence being that in the United States the advancement of 
 labor was retarded by immigration. He overlooks, however, 
 the fact that the period of German industrial expansion was 
 also a period of immigration of Polish and Italian workers 
 to Germany. Thus improvement of the condition of labor 
 came along with immigration. 
 
 But, cleverly interjects Dr. Foerster, if statistics "really 
 prove that heavy immigration does not hurt the terms of 
 employment of labor, then they also prove that such immi- 
 gration betters the terms of employment" (p. 662). He 
 assumes that because a certain proposition is true, the con- 
 verse proposition, too, must be true. Perhaps, however, 
 one must not expect from an economic scholar a familiarity 
 with Euclid's rules of deductive reasoning. 
 
 From an economic point of view immigration is merely a 
 movement of labor to the market where there is a demand 
 
Appendix 521 
 
 for it, precisely as the movement from the country to the 
 city. Immigration to the United States supplied the un- 
 skilled labor which was wanted by the rapidly expanding 
 American industries. The expansion of industry created a 
 lively demand for skilled workers, as well as many positions 
 of a supervisory character these positions were filled by 
 native workers and older immigrants. To this extent im- 
 migration indirectly did better their terms of employment. 
 This tendency has been recognized by the experts of the 
 Immigration Commission (see p. 163). 
 
 On the other hand, reduction of the supply of labor, in- 
 stead of raising wages, may react upon the demand for labor. 
 A demonstration was furnished by the "non-essential" in- 
 dustries during the late war. The supply of foreign labor 
 was cut off, shortage of labor necessitated the suspension of 
 building activities, with the result that whereas from 1897 
 to 1917 relative full-time weekly earnings in the building 
 trades had grown faster than the average for ten leading 
 industries, in 1918 they fell behind the average. 1 The after- 
 effect of the suspension of building operations has been the 
 present housing crisis, which has raised the cost of shelter 
 58 per cent since the armistice. 2 This is tantamount to a 
 reduction of the real wages of the working class, as a whole, 
 for the benefit of the landlord class. 
 
 Deductive reasoning proves as fallacious in relation to 
 the problem of unemployment. Prof. Fairchild rules out all 
 the evidence disproving the hypothesis that immigration is 
 responsible for unemployment. It is wrong to assume, he 
 thinks, that the effects of immigration upon the labor market 
 must manifest themselves immediately; they may be cumu- 
 lative, and will tell a few years later, during a period of in- 
 dustrial depression. Indeed, inasmuch as over five million 
 immigrants were admitted to the United States within the 
 
 1 Douglas and Lamberson, loc. cit. t Table IV. 
 
 2 Changes in Cost of Living and Prices. Bureau of Applied Economics. 
 Bulletin No. 6, Addendum, September 25, 1920. (Estimate of the 
 National Industrial Conference Board.) 
 
522 Appendix 
 
 past ten years, and there are to-day over five million un- 
 employed in this country, is it not self-evident that had 
 those five million aliens been kept out, there would be a job 
 for everybody in this country to-day? Yet on the other 
 hand, Australia, with a total population of five millions to a 
 continent as large as the United States, and without immi- 
 gration, has also known unemployment on a scale as large 
 in proportion as the state of New York. Prof. Fairchild 
 dismisses this argument "without opinion," to use a legal 
 phrase. The fallacy of his interpretation of cyclical unem- 
 ployment lies in the ready assumption that unemployment 
 is the result of an excessive supply of labor, whereas, to 
 quote Mr. Beveridge, "it depends upon the nature of the 
 demand for labor, not upon the volume of the whole supply" 
 (see Chapter VI). The advocates of restriction of immigra- 
 tion overlook the fact that parallel with the immigration of 
 labor to the United States prior to the war there was going 
 on an immigration of European capital to the United States. 
 It was estimated that the total amount of European capital 
 invested in permanent securities and loans in the United 
 States was approximately $6, 500,000,000. l This was equal 
 to about 14 per cent of the total capital invested in American 
 industries (exclusive of agriculture). 2 The foreign-born non- 
 agricultural population constituted about the same percen- 
 tage of the total non-agricultural population of the United 
 States. 3 In other words, European capital came together 
 
 1 George Paish, The Trade Balance of the United States, pp. 174, 175. 
 (Senate Document 579, Sixty-first Congress, 2d Session.) 
 
 1 The wealth invested in mines and quarries, factory land and im- 
 provements, manufacturing machinery, products of mining and manu- 
 facturing in stock, steam railroads, canals and shipping, telegraphs, 
 telephones, street railways, central electric light and power stations, 
 private waterworks, and other business property, was estimated for 
 1904 at $46,900,000,000. Wealth, Debt, and Taxation (Bureau of Cen- 
 sus), pp. 12, 17, 22, 27. 
 
 8 The proportion of foreign-born among the farmers in the United 
 States was 13.2 per cent in 1900 (Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 
 XXXVI., p. cxiii.), i.e. t approximately the same as among the popula- 
 tion at large. 
 
Appendix 523 
 
 with European labor to assist in the development of American 
 industry. 
 
 The Immigration Commission contended that there was, 
 nevertheless, an oversupply of unskilled labor due to immi- 
 gration. The guiding idea of its report is the belief that 
 native Americans and older immigrant workers had been 
 displaced by recent immigrants. In support of this theory 
 the Commission quoted census statistics for the decade 1890- 
 1900. On closer examination, however, the figures of the 
 censuses of 1890 and 1900 proved quite the opposite of what 
 the Commission intended to prove. Yet Prof. Fairchild 
 would not give up a hypothesis merely for want of facts to 
 support it. The decade 1890-1900, he objects, is incon- 
 clusive, because it was a period of light immigration, but if 
 the author had consulted the figures of the XIII. Census, 
 which followed a decade of heavy immigration, they would 
 tell another story. Regardless of the general rule that the 
 burden of proof is not on the negative, but on the affirmative 
 in the present case, upon that side which affirms the theory 
 of "racial displacement" it is characteristic of Prof. Fair- 
 child's easy methods of reasoning that at the time he made 
 this guess the occupation statistics of the XIII. Census had 
 not yet been published, so he manifestly did not know what 
 they would show. 
 
 The present writer was not satisfied, however, to rest his 
 conclusions on the period relied upon by the Immigration 
 Commission, but, anticipating such hypothetical objections 
 as those of Prof. Fairchild, he perused the report of the 
 Massachusetts state census of 1905, which showed "no ma- 
 terial change in the make-up of the industrial forces during 
 the first five years of the present century" (see p. 176). 
 The years 1900-1905 were marked by heavy immigration; 
 the total for the five-year period, 3,841,646, exceeded the 
 total for the previous decade; 1 the net immigration for the 
 five calendar years 1900-1904, preceding the Massachusetts 
 state census, was nearly equal to the net immigration for the 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. i, pp. 56, 57. 
 
524 Appendix 
 
 next five years, 1905-1909, preceding the XIII. Census of 
 the United States (see Table 8, on p. 90) ; Massachusetts is 
 one of the states with a large immigrant population. In 
 the absence of any data to the contrary, the results of the 
 Massachusetts census could properly be accepted as an indi- 
 cation that the data for 1890-1900 still held good in 1910. 
 
 The XIII. Census report on occupations was subsequently 
 published in an uncompleted form, with a new classification 
 which rendered its figures non-comparable with those of the 
 preceding censuses. 
 
 Another of the popular myths related to the subject of 
 labor supply is the alleged "stimulation" of immigration. 
 The author has quoted the statement of the Immigration 
 Commission that "owing to the rigidity of the law and the 
 fact that special provision is made for its enforcement, there 
 are probably at the present time relatively few actual con- 
 tract laborers admitted." This does not satisfy Prof. Fair- 
 child. He insinuates that the author has deliberately omitted 
 other qualifying statements of the Commission. He quotes a 
 sentence to the effect that "a very large number . . . come 
 in response to indirect assurance that employment awaits 
 them" (which, as a matter of fact, he could have found on 
 p. 94 of this book, reproduced in almost identical language 
 from another page of the same volume). He further quotes 
 the opinion of the Commission that "it is certain that Euro- 
 pean immigrants, and particularly those from southern and 
 eastern Europe, are, under a literal construction of the law, 
 for the most part contract laborers" (p. 761). He is not dis- 
 turbed by the glaring contradiction between this conclusion 
 and the other that "owing to the rigidity of the law" and its 
 effective enforcement there are "few actual contract laborers 
 admitted." He fails to perceive the distinction between a 
 statement of facts and a conclusion, and is apparently un- 
 familiar with the time-honored rule of evidence that one 
 may accept the testimony of witnesses concerning facts, 
 without accepting their conclusions from those facts. 
 
 Closely connected with the subject of unemployment is 
 
Appendix 525 
 
 the effect of machinery upon the demand for labor. Here 
 again deductive reasoning has failed our learned economists. 
 Prof. Fairchild denies "the assumption (sic!) that labor- 
 saving machinery supplants skilled labor to a much greater 
 extent than unskilled labor" (p. 763). He is seconded by 
 Dr. Foerster, who has picked out a number of exceptions, of 
 which only one need be mentioned here: "The old cobbler 
 was not superior to the worker in the modern shoe industry" 
 (p. 665). He should brush up on his Taussig, where he will 
 find the following: 
 
 The cobbler of former days put together a shoe by himself; in a 
 modern factory the shoe goes through some eighty different processes. 
 . . . The machines now used . . . have extended the principle of the 
 automatic repetition of identical movements to tasks long thought 
 too intricate to be amenable to such methods. . . . The skillful work- 
 man and the adaptable tool retain a large place in industry; but the 
 range of their work tends to become more and more restricted. 1 
 
 This proposition has become a truism. The author has 
 quoted a statement of Professors Jenks and Lauck which in- 
 cidentally refers to the fact that "the invention of mechan- 
 ical methods and processes" has resulted in the employment 
 of "unskilled industrial workers as a substitute for the 
 
 1 Principles of Economics, by F. W. Taussig, vol. i, pp. 35-36. That 
 the theory originated by Prof. Fairchild and Dr. Foerster had been 
 unknown to their predecessors in the field of economics, appears from 
 the following references: "The effect of improvements in machinery," 
 according to an early writer, consists "in substituting one description 
 of human labor for another the less skilled for the more skilled." 
 Andrew Ure: The Philosophy of Manufactures, p. 321 (Third edition, 
 London, 1861). "A factor that has had a real tendency to lower the 
 actual average earnings of the wage-earner in many of the industries is 
 the displacement of the skilled operative by machinery, which permits 
 the substitution of a comparatively unskilled machine hand. This 
 tendency is noticeable in many lines of industry." Twelfth Census, 
 Manufactures, vol. i, p. 123. President McKinley's Industrial Commis- 
 sion, discussing the effects of immigration upon wages, remarked that 
 "machinery ... by displacing the skilled mechanic, makes room for the 
 unskilled immigrant." Report of the Industrial Commission, vol. xv, 
 p. xxiii. 
 
f 
 
 526 Appendix 
 
 skilled operatives formerly required" (see p. 290). That in 
 some cases the machine has substituted a new kind of skill 
 for the old one, may be conceded. But the error is in the 
 deductive reasoning from insufficient facts, which are gen- 
 eralized out of all proportion to their real place in modern 
 industry. If Dr. Foerster had taken note of the statistics 
 compiled by Mr. Fitch in his study of the steel workers 
 (reproduced in Table 121 of this book) he would realize that 
 the skilled workers constitute only about one-sixth of the 
 force of a modern steel plant, whereas more than three-fifths 
 are unskilled laborers. Owing to his misconception of the 
 effects of machinery he fails to "see that the introduction of 
 new labor-saving machinery as a substitute for immigration 
 would displace the skilled labor of the native American 
 workers and reduce them to the condition of unskilled 
 laborers (see Chapter XXIII). 
 
 The contempt of both reviewers for facts is reflected in 
 their judgments on every economic and social problem. 
 Discrimination between recent immigrants from southern 
 and eastern Europe and older immigrants from northern 
 and western Europe, runs through the whole report of the 
 Immigration Commission, yet Dr. Foerster wonders, are 
 there really "persons who ask for restriction on the ground 
 that former immigrants were 'more desirable' than the 
 present ones"? (p. 658). He ridicules the idea that "a re- 
 duction in the day's work, all other things being equal, pro- 
 vides more days of work for every employee." Yet it is a 
 fact that the American Federation of Labor has repeatedly 
 urged the shortening of the work day on this very ground. 1 
 
 Prof. Fairchild, speaking of child labor, says: 
 
 The only reasonable basis of comparison is the total number of chil- 
 dren of the given ages in each nativity group in the country. If the 
 author had made this comparison ... it would have appeared that 
 nearly three times as large a percentage of all children of foreign parents, 
 
 l See Report on Unemployment, by" John Koren, in "Waste in In- 
 dustry," by The Committee on Elimination of Waste in Industry of 
 the Federated Engineering Societies (1921), p. 296. 
 
Appendix 527 
 
 of the given ages, are employed in the specified occupations as children of 
 native parents (p. 762). 
 
 As a matter of fact, the author did make such a compari- 
 son in Table 94, on p. 320, with the result that the percentage 
 of children of foreign parents employed in manufactures was 
 found to be exactly the same as that of children of native 
 parents, and not "three times as large," as Prof. Fairchild 
 imagines. 
 
 Dr. Foerster interprets the employment of children in 
 large numbers in the Southern mills as the effect of immi- 
 gration. The Southern manufacturers are compelled to em- 
 ploy children in order to meet the competition of the cheap 
 immigrant labor of the North. Reference to Table 114 
 shows, however, that the average yearly earnings of adult 
 males in the cotton mills of South Carolina were at the cen- 
 sus of manufactures of 1905 about equal to the earnings of 
 children in the cotton mills of Massachusetts ($244 and 
 $233, respectively), and that the earnings of adult males in 
 Pennsylvania were more than double the earnings of adult 
 males in North and South Carolina. It was a case of the 
 native Southerner underbidding the immigrant. The ab- 
 sence of adequate laws against child labor in the South is 
 thus obviously due to the demand for labor, not for cheap 
 labor adult male labor is cheap enough in the South. In 
 the Ncrth, too, child labor was employed in the early days of 
 the cotton manufacturing industry; later, however, with the 
 growth of immigration, the cotton mills secured a supply of 
 adult labor which made it practicable to dispense with 
 child labor (see Chapter XIV). 
 
 In reference to pauperism, Dr. Fairchild boldly asserts 
 that it would be difficult to find "statistics which would not 
 go to show that the amount of pauperism among the foreign- 
 born was vastly out of proportion to their total numbers in the 
 population'' (p. 762). It does not matter that Tables 106- 
 109 do present such statistics, drawn from official sources, 
 and that the Immigration Commission, though unfriendly to 
 immigration, after an investigation which covered the activi- 
 
528 Appendix 
 
 ties of associated charities in forty-three cities, came to the 
 conclusion that "the recent immigrants, even in cities in 
 times of relative industrial inactivity, did not seek charitable 
 assistance in any considerable numbers" (p. 354). 
 
 A brief chapter has been devoted by the author to the 
 refutation of Gen. Walker's theory that immigration has 
 displaced millions of unborn Americans. To Prof. Fairchild's 
 mind, however, the reiteration of Gen. Walker's hypothesis 
 by other prominent writers (none of whom has contributed 
 a single new fact in support of it) somehow vests it with 
 added authority. Magister dixit. He is not disturbed by 
 his own admission, in his book published a short time before, 
 that "the proposition ... is absolutely incapable of mathe- 
 matical proof." l 
 
 To prove that the world-wide "volitional limitation of the 
 family" has no relation to immigration to the United States, 
 figures were quoted, in the first edition of this book, from 
 Mr. Newsholme's The Declining Birth Rate, showing the num- 
 ber of children born to an average family of the British aris- 
 tocracy to have declined within half a century from 7 to 3.* 
 The decline of the birth-rate among the upper classes of Eng- 
 land led Prof. Karl Pearson to the following conclusions: 
 
 The mentally better stock in the nation is not reproducing itself at 
 the same rate as of old. . . . For the last forty years the intellectual 
 classes of the nation, enervated by wealth or by love of pleasure, or 
 following an erroneous standard of life, have ceased to give in due pro- 
 portion the men wanted to carry on the ever-growing work of the 
 Empire. 8 
 
 Still, if facts do not count with Prof. Fairchild against a 
 preconceived idea backed up by authorities, the authority 
 of Prof. Willcox, ranged on the opposite side of the question, 
 
 1 Henry Pratt Fairchild: Immigration^ pp. 341-342. 
 
 * These statistics have since been superseded by a nation-wide inves- 
 tigation, the results of which are quoted in the present edition. 
 
 ' Quoted in the first edition, p. 226, from The Declining Birth Rate, 
 by Arthur Newsholme, pp. 42-43. 
 
Appendix 529 
 
 ought to have appealed to him. That he has not a word to 
 say about Prof. Willcox's arguments, although he has 
 noticed the wrong spelling of Prof. Willcox's name, is ground 
 for suspicion that he did not read the chapter on Race 
 Suicide, and based his peremptory judgment on the brief 
 summary on p. 18. 
 
 Verily, there are none so blind as those who would not 
 see. 
 
Appendix 
 
 Note to page 499. 
 
 IMPORTATION OF MEXICAN CONTRACT-LABORERS. 
 
 Under the departmental regulations, Mexican contract laborers are 
 admitted on the express condition that they will remain at work with 
 the employer by whom they were imported. If a contract laborer de- 
 serts his employer and attempts to seek work elsewhere, he is to be 
 deported from the United States. There is a possibility that a contract 
 laborer who has deserted his employer might successfully conceal his 
 identity and find other employment. To guard against such an emer- 
 gency the employer is required to withhold a part of the wages of the 
 contract laborer, pending the fulfillment of his contract, and to deposit 
 the same with a postal savings bank in the name of the laborer. In 
 case the latter deserts, he forfeits the amount deposited for his benefit. 
 To be sure, the regulations require the employer to pay his contract 
 laborers the prevailing rate of wages. 1 But this is merely nudum jus, 
 which could not be enforced in practice. Suppose the employer pays his 
 imported laborer under the prevailing rate, what remedy has the latter 
 to enforce his claim? He dare not leave his job and seek employment 
 on better terms, for fear of deportation. For the same reason he dare 
 not strike for higher wages. He must accept the wages stipulated in 
 his contract (made in Mexico) although they may be below the pre- 
 vailing rate paid for the same work in the same locality. "That wages 
 paid and conditions provided" for the imported Mexican laborers were 
 "perhaps in many cases not ideal," is admitted in a report of an investi- 
 gating committee appointed by Secretary Wilson. It is learned from 
 the same report that 10,691 imported contract laborers, i.e., 21 per 
 cent of the total number, deserted. 8 
 
 1 "The New Mexican Immigration," by J. B. Gwin: The Survey, 
 August 3, 1918, p. 491. 
 1 Monthly Labor Review, November, 1920, p. 223. 
 
STATISTICAL TABLES 
 
 TABLE I. ANNUAL AVERAGE IMMIGRATION DISTRIBUTED BY OCCUPA* 
 TIONS (IN THOUSANDS), 1.861-1910. x 
 
 Occupation 
 
 1861-1870 
 
 1871-1880 
 
 1881-1890 
 
 1891-1900 
 
 1901-1910 
 
 Professional 
 
 i 
 
 2 
 
 3* 
 
 2 
 
 IO 
 
 Skilled 
 
 ^o 
 
 j-i 
 
 CA 
 
 AA 
 
 1^2 
 
 Agricultural pursuits, 
 total 
 
 22 
 
 26 
 
 17 
 
 2<\ 
 
 TCQ 
 
 Common laborers .... 
 
 C-I 
 
 60 
 
 I-I-I 
 
 IO1 
 
 *ov 
 
 227 
 
 Servants . 
 
 9 
 
 II 
 
 25 
 
 l-I 
 
 O2 
 
 All other occupations. . . 
 
 10 
 
 II 
 
 13 
 
 12 
 
 33 
 
 Total 
 
 125 
 
 14. t 
 
 265 
 
 210 
 
 651 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TABLE II: FLUCTUATIONS OF EMPLOYMENT OF MALE WAGE-EARNERS 
 IN THE MONTH OF MAY, 1899.* 
 
 Greatest number laid off 
 Industry 
 
 Glucose 
 
 Fur hats 
 
 Jewelry 
 
 Steam fittings and heating apparatus 
 
 Number 
 1,267 
 1,650 
 1,924 
 1, 680 
 
 Total. 
 
 6,521 
 
 * Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance, June, 1903, pp. 4408- 
 44 1 1 . Reports of the Immigration Commission. A bstract of the Statistical 
 Review of Immigration to the United States, 1820-1910, Tables 11-12. 
 Annual Reports of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1899, Table 
 VII.,p. 19; 1900, Table VII., p. 21; 1901, Table IX., p. 26; 1902, Table 
 IX., p. 29; 1903, Table IX., p. 33; 1904, Table IX., p. 30; 1905, 
 Table VIII., p. 29; 1906, Table VIIL, p. 31; 1907, Table VIII., p. 31; 
 1908, Table VIII., p. 35; 1909, Table X., p. 46; 1910, Table X., p. 45. 
 
 a Compiled from U. S. XII. Census Report on Manufactures, Pt. I, 
 Table 2, pp. 20 et se^. 
 
 a Difference between the greatest number employed at any time 
 during the year and the number employed in May (i.e., the least number). 
 
 531 
 
532 Appendix 
 
 TABLE II. (Continued). 
 
 Greatest number of temporary Help wanted.* 
 
 Industry Numbet 
 
 Awnings, tents, and sails 1,312 
 
 Bags, paper 33 8 
 
 Baskets and rattan and willow ware 1 ,889 
 
 Belting and hose, leather 63 
 
 Blacksmithing and wheel wrighting 345 
 
 Boxes, wooden packing 2,771 
 
 Brass castings and brass finishings 7 21 
 
 Bread and other bakery products 2,661 
 
 Bicycle and tricycle repairing 3,696 
 
 Carpets, rag 290 
 
 Carriages and wagons 14> l8 7 
 
 Cars, general shop construction and repairs by street 
 
 railroad companies 57^ 
 
 Cheese, butter, and condensed milk, factory product 5,789 
 
 Clothing, men's, custom work and repairing 16,861 
 
 Cork, cutting 123 
 
 Corsets 84 
 
 Dyeing and cleaning 771 
 
 Dyestuffs and extracts 178 
 
 Electroplating 483 
 
 Furniture, cabinetmaking, repairing and upholstering .... 2,384 
 
 Gas, machines and meters 193 
 
 Gloves and mittens 561 
 
 Grease and tallow 142 
 
 Grindstones 487 
 
 Hosiery and knit goods 1,723 
 
 Lamps and reflectors 439 
 
 Lock and gun smithing 100 
 
 Lumber, planing mill products, including sash, doors, and 
 
 blinds 13,399 
 
 Lumber and timber products 93,238 
 
 Monuments and tombstones 4,43 
 
 Painting, house, sign, etc 48,838 
 
 Paperhanging 5,637 
 
 Paper and wood pulp 4,002 
 
 Photographic materials 55 
 
 Pipes, tobacco 138 
 
 Plumbers' supplies 7 834 
 
 Refrigerators 383 
 
 1 Difference between the number employed in May (i.e., the greatest 
 number) and the least number employed at any time during the year. 
 
Appendix 
 
 533 
 
 TABLE II. (Concluded). 
 
 Industry 
 
 Safes and vaults 
 
 Ship and boat building, wooden 
 
 Slaughtering, wholesale, not including packing. 
 
 Tin and terae plate 
 
 Tobacco, chewing, smoking, and snuff 
 
 Tobacco, cigars, and cigarettes 
 
 Washing machines and clothes wringers 
 
 Window shades 
 
 Zinc, smelting and refining 
 
 Total. . 
 
 Number 
 
 137 
 
 5,346 
 
 743 
 
 1.594 
 
 3,983 
 
 6,348 
 
 212 
 247 
 590 
 
 252,01 7 
 
 TABLE III. MAXIMUM AND MINIMUM NUMBER OF WAGE-EARNERS EMPLOYED n 
 MANUFACTURES DURING ANY ONE MONTH, NUMBER AND PER CENT UNEM 
 PLOYED, 1899, AND PER CENT FOREIGN-BORN ENGAGED IN MANUFACTURED 
 AND MECHANICAL PURSUITS, 1900, BY SEX AND BY STATES.' 
 
 Rank ace ord- 
 
 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 
 ing to 
 
 
 Number employed 
 
 
 
 ; per cent 
 
 State* 
 
 (oo's omitted) 
 
 4 
 
 :|! 
 
 . 
 
 . 
 
 I .-A 
 
 8>H 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 So 
 
 8 g g 
 
 *1 
 
 P 
 
 1* 
 
 
 Maximum month 
 
 Minimum month 
 
 *! 
 
 *liS 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 I. MALES 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 i 
 
 5 
 
 North Carolina 
 
 May 47,9 
 
 August 42,5 
 
 5,4 
 
 11.3 
 
 1.0 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 South Carolina 
 
 November 32,8 
 
 July 26,0 
 
 6,8 
 
 20.5 
 
 1.7 
 
 3 
 
 19 
 
 Georgia 
 
 March 70,2 
 
 July 59.9 
 
 10,3 
 
 14.6 
 
 2.8 
 
 4 
 
 
 Virginia 
 
 May 60,0 
 
 January 52,0 
 
 8,0 
 
 13.3 
 
 3-9 
 
 
 i 
 
 Tennessee 
 
 May 44.4 
 
 August 41,0 
 
 3,4 
 
 7.7 
 
 4-5 
 
 5 
 
 42 
 
 Mississippi 
 
 October 28,4 
 
 July 19,6 
 
 8,8 
 
 31.0 
 
 4.6 
 
 7 
 
 25 
 
 Alabama 
 
 October 49,2 
 
 July 40,3 
 
 8,9 
 
 18.1 
 
 5-5 
 
 8 
 
 33 
 
 Arkansas 
 
 November 28,5 
 
 July 22,1 
 
 6,4 
 
 22.5 
 
 6.4 
 
 9 
 
 35 
 
 Oklahoma 
 
 May 2,2 
 
 July i,7 
 
 5 
 
 22.7 
 
 9.0 
 
 10 
 
 ii 
 
 12 
 
 17 
 
 22 
 
 47 
 
 West Virginia 
 Kentucky 
 Louisiana 
 
 May 31,9 
 May 56,9 
 November 54,3 
 
 July 27,4 
 January 48,0 
 July 28,3 
 
 4,5 
 8,9 
 26,0 
 
 14.1 
 15-6 
 
 47-9 
 
 10.3 
 
 "5 
 12.4 
 
 13 
 
 43 
 
 District of 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Columbia 
 
 September 16,7 
 
 February 11,1 
 
 5.6 
 
 33-5 
 
 13-0 
 
 14 
 
 13 
 
 Indiana 
 
 May 144.5 
 
 December 125,3 
 
 19,2 
 
 13-3 
 
 14.7 
 
 15 
 
 16 
 
 48 
 36 
 
 Indian Territory 
 Florida 
 
 November 2,4 
 March 36,0 
 
 June 1,1 
 July 27,8 
 
 1,3 
 8,2 
 
 54-2 
 
 22.8 
 
 15-2 
 1 6.0 
 
 17 
 
 20 
 
 Delaware 
 
 September 19,2 
 
 February 16,3 
 
 2.9 
 
 i5-i 
 
 17.7 
 
 18 
 
 24 
 
 Maryland 
 
 September 80,2 
 
 January 66,6 
 
 13,6 
 
 16.8 
 
 18.4 
 
 ' Compiled from XII. Census Report on Manufactures, Vol. I, Table 3, pp. 62-63 
 
 Occupations at the XII. Census, p. 164, Table 34. 
 a States where the number of males or females, respectively, employed durinj 
 
 the maximum month was less than 1000, are not included. 
 
534 
 
 TABLE III. (Continued) 
 
 Appendix 
 
 Rank a 
 
 ing 
 perc 
 
 
 
 fj 
 
 ccord- 
 to 
 ent 
 
 M ^ ~ 
 
 il 
 
 <* 
 
 State 
 
 Number employed 
 (oo's omitted) 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 (Per cent 
 
 foreign-born 
 
 Number 
 (oo's omitted) 
 
 Per cent of 
 greatest num- 
 ber employedj 
 
 Maximum month 
 
 Minimum month 
 
 19 
 
 44 
 
 Texas 
 
 October 56,5 
 
 June 37,6 
 
 18,9 
 
 33-5 
 
 18.9 
 
 2O 
 
 23 
 
 Kansas t 
 
 May 33,3 
 
 January 27,8 
 
 5,5 
 
 16.4 
 
 194 
 
 21 
 
 27 
 
 Missouri 
 
 May 115,2 
 
 January 93,1 
 
 22,1 
 
 19.2 
 
 2O.6 
 
 22 
 
 10 
 
 Ohio 
 
 May 304,6 
 
 January 266,5 
 
 38,1 
 
 12.5 
 
 24.1 
 
 23 
 
 38 
 
 Maine 
 
 September 60,6 
 
 January 45,5 
 
 15,1 
 
 24.9 
 
 24.2 
 
 24 
 
 39 
 
 Iowa 
 
 September 54,9 
 
 January 40,0 
 
 14,9 
 
 27.2 
 
 26.5 
 
 3 
 
 40 
 
 21 
 
 Oregon 
 Vermont 
 
 June 1 6, 9 
 May 26,9 
 
 January 12,3 
 January 22,8 
 
 4,6 
 4,1 
 
 27.2 
 15-2 
 
 28.8 
 29.6 
 
 27 
 
 2 
 
 New Mexico 
 
 May 2,6 
 
 February 2,4 
 
 2 
 
 7-7 
 
 30.c 
 
 28 
 
 26 
 
 Nebraska 
 
 September 22,6 
 
 February 18,4 
 
 4,2 
 
 18.6 
 
 30.7 
 
 29 
 
 45 
 
 Idaho 
 
 May 1,7 
 
 anuary I ,i 
 
 6 
 
 35-3 
 
 
 30 
 
 7 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 May 596,7 
 
 January 531,5 
 
 65,5 
 
 II.O 
 
 33-2 
 
 3 1 
 
 3 1 
 
 California 
 
 September 80,4 
 
 January 63,2 
 
 16,9 
 
 2I.O 
 
 34-4 
 
 32 
 
 
 Washington 
 
 May 38,0 
 
 January 27,0 
 
 11,0 
 
 29.0 
 
 34-9 
 
 33 
 
 3 
 
 New Hampshire 
 
 May 49,o 
 
 [anuary 45,0 
 
 4,0 
 
 8.2 
 
 f\ 
 
 37-8 
 
 34 
 
 18 
 
 Arizona 
 
 May 3,5 
 
 November 3,0 
 
 5 
 
 14.2 
 
 37-5 
 
 35 
 
 16 
 
 Colorado 
 
 October 24,3 
 
 February 21,0 
 
 3,3 
 
 13-6 
 
 J 
 
 38.4 
 
 36 
 
 12 
 
 New Jersey 
 
 May 191,6 
 
 January 166,4 
 
 25,2 
 
 13.2 
 
 38-S 
 
 37 
 
 II 
 
 Wyoming 
 
 August 2,3 
 
 February 2,0 
 
 3 
 
 13-0 
 
 40.$ 
 
 38 
 
 6 
 
 Connecticut 
 
 May 135,2 
 
 January 121,2 
 
 14,0 
 
 IO.4 
 
 
 39 
 
 15 
 
 Illinois 
 
 May 345,7 
 
 January 299,2 
 
 46,5 
 
 13-5 
 
 44-* 
 
 40 
 
 28 
 
 Michigan 
 
 May 151,2 
 
 January 121,6 
 
 29,6 
 
 19.6 
 
 44-* 
 
 41 
 
 32 
 
 Wisconsin 
 
 May 134,0 
 
 January 104,1 
 
 29,9 
 
 22.3 
 
 44-* 
 
 42 
 43 
 
 8 
 4 
 
 New York 
 Massachusetts 
 
 May 639,9 
 October 355,2 
 
 January 564,5 
 January 322,8 
 
 75,4 
 32,4 
 
 H.8 
 9.1 
 
 44-5 
 46.3 
 
 44 
 
 37 
 
 Utah 
 
 September 6,2 
 
 February 4,7 
 
 
 24.2 
 
 
 45 
 
 9 
 
 Rhode Island 
 
 September 66,9 
 
 January 59,0 
 
 7\9 
 
 11.8 
 
 47.C 
 
 46 
 
 29 
 
 Montana 
 
 May 10,6 
 
 February 8,5 
 
 2,1 
 
 19.8 
 
 CJ 
 
 47 
 
 46 
 
 North Dakota 
 
 September 2,7 
 
 February 1 ,6 
 
 1,1 
 
 40.7 
 
 53-! 
 
 48 
 
 34 
 
 Minnesota 
 
 May 74,2 
 
 January 57,5 
 
 16,7 
 
 22.5 
 
 \j*j ^ 
 53-* 
 
 
 
 UNITED STATES 
 
 May 4333,9 
 
 January 3800,9 
 
 533,o 
 
 12.3 
 
 32-; 
 
 
 
 II. FEMALES 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 5 
 
 North Carolina 
 
 May 16,7 
 
 July 14,7 
 
 2,0 
 
 12.0 
 
 O.2 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 South Carolina 
 
 March 10,1 
 
 September 9,3 
 
 8 
 
 7-9 
 
 
 3 
 
 ii 
 
 Georgia 
 
 April 11,6 
 
 Bily 10,0 
 
 1,6 
 
 13-8 
 
 o.; 
 
 4 
 
 34 
 
 Mississippi 
 
 October 2,1 
 
 ily 1,4 
 
 7 
 
 33-3 
 
 o.f 
 
 5 
 
 24 
 
 Alabama 
 
 May 4,3 
 
 dy 3,3 
 
 1,0 
 
 23-3 
 
 I.C 
 
 6 
 
 H 
 
 Virginia 
 
 October 13,2 
 
 ily ii, i 
 
 2,1 
 
 15-9 
 
 i.t 
 
 7 
 
 8 
 
 Tennessee 
 
 May 6,2 
 
 ebruary 54 
 
 8 
 
 12.9 
 
 j i 
 
 8 
 
 30 
 
 West Virginia 
 
 October 4,0 
 
 July 2,8 
 
 
 30.0 
 
 3- ( 
 
 9 
 
 10 
 
 23 
 
 Kentucky 
 Indiana 
 
 April 1 0,0 
 September 22,8 
 
 August 7,8 
 July 15,9 
 
 2 ',2 
 
 6,9 
 
 22.0 
 30.3 
 
 4.1 
 5-4 
 
Appendix 
 
 S3S 
 
 TABLE III. (Concluded). 
 
 iank accord- 
 
 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 
 ing to 
 per cent 
 
 Of A+jh 
 
 Number employed 
 (oo's omitted) 
 
 
 tij 
 
 3 
 
 f| 
 
 Sd 
 
 e* 
 
 DlabC 
 
 
 |i 
 
 5*1 
 
 Jj-5? 
 
 9P 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 y g 8 
 
 PH K 
 
 jr 
 
 C O 
 PP, 
 
 
 Maximum month 
 
 Minimum month 
 
 g 
 
 <g|g 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ' i 
 
 
 
 
 ii 
 
 19 
 
 Louisiana 
 
 Vfarch ) , n 
 December f 6 ' 
 
 July 4,8 
 
 1,2 
 
 20.0 
 
 5-6 
 
 12 
 
 36 
 
 District of 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Columbia 
 
 April 2,2 
 
 August 1,3 
 
 9 
 
 40.9 
 
 5-9 
 
 13 
 
 28 
 
 Kansas 
 
 October 3,7 
 
 February 2,7 
 
 1,0 
 
 27.0 
 
 6-5 
 
 14 
 
 37 
 
 Delaware 
 
 September 5,8 
 
 uly 2,4 
 
 3,4 
 
 58.6 
 
 6.6 
 
 15 
 
 16 
 
 Missouri 
 
 September 25,7 
 
 July 20,6 
 
 
 19.8 
 
 8.4 
 
 16 
 
 29 
 
 Iowa 
 
 September 9,5 
 
 January 6,8 
 
 2 ',7 
 
 28.4 
 
 9.6 
 
 17 
 
 27 
 
 Maryland 
 
 September 36,0 
 
 February 26,3 
 
 9,7 
 
 26.9 
 
 9-7 
 
 18 
 
 9 
 
 Ohio 
 
 Dctober 56,9 
 
 January 49,4 
 
 7,5 
 
 13-2 
 
 IO.O 
 
 19 
 
 25 
 
 Texas 
 
 May 3,4 
 
 August 2,5 
 
 9 
 
 26.5 
 
 10.4 
 
 20 
 
 33 
 
 Oregon 
 
 September 2,2 
 
 August 1 ,5 
 
 7 
 
 31-8 
 
 12.4 
 
 21 
 
 6 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 April 131,6 
 
 July 115,8 
 
 15,8 
 
 12.0 
 
 13-0 
 
 22 
 
 12 
 
 Vermont 
 
 April 4,8 
 
 July 4,1 
 
 7 
 
 14.6 
 
 14.6 
 
 23 
 
 32 
 
 Colorado 
 
 October 2,3 
 
 January 1 ,6 
 
 7 
 
 304 
 
 14.8 
 
 24 
 
 26 
 
 Nebraska 
 
 October 3,0 
 
 January 2,2 
 
 8 
 
 26.7 
 
 15-8 
 
 25 
 
 38 
 
 California 
 
 August 27,6 
 
 August 1 1 ,4 
 
 16,2 
 
 58-7 
 
 17.0 
 
 26 
 
 27 
 
 21 
 15 
 
 Washington 
 Wisconsin 
 
 May 1,4 
 October 17,4 
 
 August 1,1 
 ; anuary 14,6 
 
 2,8 
 
 21.4 
 
 16.1 
 
 19.1 
 19.9 
 
 28 
 
 35 
 
 Florida 
 
 March 2 ,o 
 
 July 1,3 
 
 7 
 
 35- 
 
 20.3 
 
 29 
 30 
 31 
 
 18 
 
 10 
 
 20 
 
 Michigan 
 New Jersey 
 Illinois 
 
 October 25,6 
 October 55,1 
 April 64,1 
 
 July 20,5 
 July 47,7 
 July 51,6 
 
 74 
 12,5 
 
 19.9 
 134 
 19-5 
 
 22.7 
 25-2 
 26.1 
 
 32 
 
 22 
 
 Minnesota 
 
 May 10,5 
 
 July 8,2 
 
 2,3 
 
 21.9 
 
 27.0 
 
 33 
 
 4 
 
 Connecticut 
 
 October 44,3 
 
 January 40,7 
 
 3,6 
 
 8.1 
 
 27.9 
 
 34 
 
 13 
 
 New York 
 
 October 244,4 
 
 'uly 208,0 
 
 364 
 
 14.9 
 
 29.6 
 
 35 
 
 17 
 
 Maine 
 
 October 21,1 
 
 February 16,9 
 
 4,2 
 
 19.9 
 
 32.8 
 
 36 
 
 2 
 
 Rhode Island 
 
 December 30,8 
 
 August 28,^ 
 
 2,4 
 
 7.8 
 
 39-5 
 
 37 
 
 7 
 
 Massachusetts 
 
 April 149,5 
 
 August 130,6 
 
 18,9 
 
 12.6 
 
 40.6 
 
 38 
 
 i 
 
 New Hampshire 
 
 December 22,5 
 
 August 21,1 
 
 1,4 
 
 6.2 
 
 46.2 
 
 
 
 UNITED STATES 
 
 October 1089,8 
 
 July 949,3 
 
 I4<>5 
 
 12.9 
 
 214 
 
536 Appendix 
 
 TABLE IV. PERCENTAGE RATIOS OF UNEMPLOYED AND OF FOREUM 
 
 Rank according 
 
 
 
 
 to per cent 
 
 
 
 
 - 
 
 | 
 
 Occupation 
 
 Unemployed a* 
 any time during 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 } 
 
 I 
 
 
 the year 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 Males 
 Telegraph and telephone 
 
 
 
 
 
 operators. 
 
 9 .6 
 
 6.3 
 
 2 
 
 34 
 
 Confectioners. 
 
 II.2 
 
 35-9 
 
 3 
 
 47 
 
 Bakers. 
 
 H.3 
 
 56.4 
 
 4 
 
 32 
 
 Butchers. 
 
 H.5 
 
 35-2 
 
 5 
 
 49 
 
 Brewers and maltsters. 
 
 I2.I 
 
 71.9 
 
 6 
 
 27 
 
 Bartenders. 
 
 12.5 
 
 31.1 
 
 I 
 
 7 
 37 
 
 Porters and helpers (in stores). 
 Cotton mill operatives. 
 
 12.6 
 
 19.8 
 38.3 
 
 9 
 
 
 Street railway employees. 
 
 13-3 
 
 24.2 
 
 10 
 
 19 
 
 Machinists. 
 
 134 
 
 27.7 
 
 ii 
 
 18 
 
 Blacksmiths. 
 
 13.7 
 
 / / 
 
 27.7 
 
 12 
 
 5 
 
 Printers, lithographers, and 
 
 
 / / 
 
 
 
 pressmen. 
 
 15-0 
 
 I 5-9 
 
 13 
 
 10 
 
 Steam railroad employees. 
 
 15-8 
 
 20.08 
 
 14 
 
 30 
 
 Paper and pulp mill 
 
 
 
 15 
 
 ii 
 
 operatives. 
 Servants and waiters. 
 
 16.9 
 I7.O 
 
 33-0 
 21.5 
 
 If 
 
 22 
 
 Steam boiler makers. 
 
 18.4 
 
 9 
 29.6 
 
 17 
 
 4 6 
 
 Bleachery and dye works 
 
 T 
 
 
 18 
 
 9 
 
 operatives. 
 Draymen, hackmen, 
 
 19-3 
 
 53-0 
 
 19 
 20 
 
 21 
 
 39 
 36 
 3 
 
 teamsters, etc. 
 Woolen mill operatives. 
 Brass workers. 
 Messenger, errand, and office 
 
 19-3 
 19-5 
 19.6 
 197 
 
 20.4 
 43-1 
 37-3 
 
 
 
 boys. 
 
 
 10 8 
 
 22 
 23 
 24 
 
 21 
 
 Upholsterers. 
 Cabinet makers. 
 Plumber and gas and steam 
 
 20.9 
 20.9 
 
 28.1 
 56.5 
 
 
 
 fitters. 
 
 22.O 
 
 IO.I 
 
 *"* 
 
 11 
 
 24 
 
 2 
 
 Tool and cutlery makers. 
 Oil well and oil works 
 
 22.0 
 
 30.2 
 
 27 
 
 38 
 
 employees. 
 Textile workers (not soe- 
 
 22.8 
 
 10.5 
 
 28 
 
 26 
 
 cified). 
 Wood workers (not spe- 
 
 23.8 
 
 41.8 
 
 29 
 30 
 
 43 
 
 cified). 
 Leather curriers and tanners. 
 Gold and silver workers. 
 
 24.6 
 24.8 
 25-3 
 
 30.8 
 47-7 
 34-5 
 
Appendix 
 
 537 
 
 WHITE BREADWINNERS IN THE PRINCIPAL OCCUPATIONS, 1900. 
 
 Rank according 
 
 
 
 
 to per cent 
 
 
 
 
 % 
 
 
 
 
 Unemployed at 
 
 
 I 
 
 | 
 
 Occupation 
 
 any time during 
 the year 
 
 White* 
 
 A 
 1 
 
 .1 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 3 1 
 
 44 
 
 Wire workers. 
 
 25.3 
 
 49-8 
 
 32 
 
 15 
 
 Tinplate and tinware makers. 
 
 25-9 
 
 24.9 
 
 33 
 
 50 
 
 Tailors. 
 
 27.0 
 
 75-8 
 
 34 
 
 29 
 
 Tobacco and cigar factory 
 
 
 
 
 
 operatives. 
 
 27.2 
 
 32.6 
 
 35 
 
 35 
 
 Iron and steel workers. 
 
 28.1 
 
 35.9 
 
 36 
 37 
 
 42 
 28 
 
 Silk mill operatives. 
 Boatmen and sailors. 
 
 29-3 
 33-3 
 
 47.1 
 31.8 
 
 38 
 39 
 
 25 
 
 Coopers. 
 Sawing and planing mill 
 
 34-3 
 
 30.8 
 
 
 
 employees. 
 
 35-1 
 
 20.1 
 
 40 
 
 41 
 
 Marble and stone cutters. 
 
 39-5 
 
 44.6 
 
 41 
 
 45 
 
 Hat and cap makers. 
 
 41.0 
 
 50.4 
 
 42 
 
 16 
 
 Carpenters and joiners. 
 
 41.4 
 
 25.4 
 
 43 
 
 *3 
 
 Painters, glaziers, and 
 
 
 
 
 
 varnishers. 
 
 42.4 
 
 23.5 
 
 44 
 
 40 
 
 Miners and quarrymen. 
 
 44-3 
 
 43.7 
 
 45 
 
 20 
 
 Laborers (not specified). 
 
 44-3 
 
 28.1 
 
 46 
 
 47 
 
 4 
 2 3 
 
 Paper hangers. 
 Brick and tile makers. 
 
 44-5 
 48.4 
 
 13.5 
 
 30.0 
 
 48 
 
 33 
 
 Masons (brick and stone). 
 
 55-5 
 
 35-3 
 
 49 
 
 17 
 
 Plasterers. 
 
 56.1 
 
 25.8 
 
 50 
 
 12 
 
 Glass workers. 
 
 59-9 
 
 22.7 
 
 
 
 Females 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 Telegraph and telephone 
 
 
 
 
 
 operators. 
 
 10.7 
 
 6.2 
 
 2 
 
 14 
 
 Servants and waitresses. 
 
 14.8 
 
 25.9 
 
 3 
 
 18 
 
 Cotton mill operatives. 
 
 14.9 
 
 38.2 
 
 4 
 
 3 
 
 Printers, lithographers, and 
 
 
 
 5 
 
 
 presswomen. 
 Bookbinders. 
 
 16.5 
 16.7 
 
 7.3 
 
 II.O 
 
 6 
 
 g 
 
 Dressmakers. 
 
 19.8 
 
 16.5 
 
 7 
 
 10 
 
 Hosiery and knitting mill 
 
 
 
 
 
 operatives. 
 
 20.0 
 
 17-9 
 
 8 
 
 7 
 
 Box makers (paper). 
 
 26.4 
 
 14.5 
 
 9 
 
 16 
 
 Woolen mill operatives. 
 
 31.1 
 
 32.1 
 
 10 
 
 Q 
 
 Shirt, collar, and cuff makers. 
 
 22.1 
 
 1 6.6 
 
 II 
 
 ;? 
 
 15 
 
 Textile workers (not specified). 
 
 22.1 
 
 30.7 
 
 12 
 
 II 
 
 Seamstresses, 
 
 24-2 
 
 18.5 
 
 1 XII. Census. Occupations, pp. ccxxvii. et seq., Tables LXXXVIIL 
 
 and LXXXIX.; pp. cxiv.-^xvi., Table XXXVII. 
 
538 Appendix 
 
 TABLE IV. (Concluded).' 
 
 Rank according 
 
 
 
 
 to per cent 
 
 
 
 
 | 
 
 3 
 1 
 
 Occupation 
 
 Unemployed at 
 any time during 
 the year 
 
 Foreign 
 
 White 
 
 
 
 .1 
 
 
 
 
 a 
 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 13 
 14 
 
 12 
 
 4 
 
 Silk mill operatives. 
 Milliners. 
 
 25.8 
 26.3 
 
 23.0 
 10.9 
 
 15 
 
 16 
 
 17 
 13 
 
 Tailors. 
 Tobacco and cigar factory 
 
 26.4 
 
 38.2 
 
 17 
 
 6 
 
 operatives. 
 Boot and shoe makers and 
 
 27.2 
 
 25.2 
 
 
 
 repairers. 
 
 42.5 
 
 I4.I 
 
 18 
 
 2 
 
 Laborers (not specified). 
 
 44.1 
 
 6.8 
 
 TABLE V. BITUMINOUS COAL MINES: GREATEST AND LEAST NUMBER 
 EMPLOYED, PER CENT UNEMPLOYED AT ANY TIME DURING THE 
 YEAR 1902, AND PER CENT FOREIGN WHITE MINERS IN 1900, IN 
 THE PRINCIPAL STATES. x 
 
 Rank according to 
 per cent 
 
 
 Number employed 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Per cent 
 
 Foreign- 
 
 Unem- 
 
 State 3 
 
 
 unem- 
 ployed 
 
 white 
 miners 
 
 
 
 born 
 
 ployed 
 
 
 Greatest 
 
 Least 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 3 
 
 Texas 
 
 2.035 
 
 1,881 
 
 7.6 
 
 62.7 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 ii 
 
 2 
 
 Wyoming 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 4,920 
 93,620 
 
 3,481 
 87,355 
 
 29.2 
 6.7 
 
 
 4 
 
 5 
 
 Illinois 
 
 39,557 
 
 32,809 
 
 I7.I 
 
 48.5 
 
 i 
 
 10 
 
 9 
 
 Iowa 
 Kansas 
 
 10,719 
 
 8,120 
 
 7,749 
 6,179 
 
 27.7 
 23-9 
 
 39-7 
 33-6 
 
 I 
 
 i 
 
 Ohio 
 IndianTerritory 
 
 27,770 
 5,109 
 
 24,241 
 4,054 
 
 12.7 
 2O.7 
 
 27-0 
 26.9 
 
 9 
 
 i 
 
 Maryland 
 
 4,881 
 
 4,706 
 
 3-6 
 
 22.3 
 
 10 
 
 ii 
 
 12 
 
 7 
 
 12 
 
 6 
 
 Indiana 
 West Virginia 
 Arkansas 
 
 11,614 
 26,197 
 2,826 
 
 9,408 
 16,564 
 2,304 
 
 19.0 
 36.7 
 18.5 
 
 21.3 
 14.3 
 13-6 
 
 1 Compiled from Census Report on Mines and Quarries, 1902, pp. 
 /IO-7I5, Table 60; Occupations at the XIL, Census, Table 41. 
 
 "All States with less than 1,000 employees have been omitted; 
 likewise New Mexico, Colorado, Missouri, and Washington, there being 
 & large number of metalliferous miners in those States who are not 
 segregated from coal miners in the census statistics of occupations. 
 
Appendix 
 
 539 
 
 TABLE VI. LABORERS, MALE: PER CENT FOREIGN WHITE AND 
 PER CENT UNEMPLOYED, BY STATES, 1900. 1 
 
 Rank according to 
 per cent 
 
 StRtO 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 Unem- 
 ployed 
 
 I 
 
 22 
 
 North Carolina . 
 
 O.I 
 
 42.1 
 
 2 
 
 5 
 
 Georgia 
 
 0.4 
 
 37-4 
 
 3 
 
 12 
 
 South Carolina 
 
 0.4 
 
 39-8 
 
 4 
 
 13 
 
 Alabama 
 
 0.6 
 
 40.6 
 
 
 36 
 
 Tennessee 
 
 0.6 
 
 45-5 
 
 6 
 
 20 
 
 Virginia 
 
 0.7 
 
 41.6 
 
 8 
 
 II 
 50 
 
 Mississippi 
 Indian Territory 
 
 0.9 
 1-5 
 
 39-7 
 65.0 
 
 9 
 
 33 
 
 Arkansas 
 
 1.6 
 
 45-o 
 
 10 
 
 6 
 
 Florida 
 
 1.7 
 
 38-0 
 
 ii 
 
 42 
 
 Kentucky 
 
 3-3 
 
 49.0 
 
 12 
 
 49 
 
 Oklahoma 
 
 3-3 
 
 56.5 
 
 13 
 
 
 District of 
 
 
 
 
 
 Columbia 
 
 4.1 
 
 38.6 
 
 14 
 
 30 
 
 West Virginia 
 
 5-5 
 
 44.2 
 
 15 
 
 26 
 
 Louisiana 
 
 5-7 
 
 43-5 
 
 10 
 
 40 
 
 Kansas 
 
 8.8 
 
 47.1 
 
 17 
 
 4 
 
 New Mexico 
 
 8-9 
 
 37-0 
 
 18 
 
 48 
 
 Indiana 
 
 9.8 
 
 52.1 
 
 19 
 
 28 
 
 Maryland 
 
 12.7 
 
 44.0 
 
 20 
 
 44 
 
 Missouri 
 
 13-3 
 
 49.4 
 
 21 
 
 23 
 
 Oregon 
 
 14.4 
 
 42.4 
 
 22 
 
 35 
 
 Texas 
 
 16.8 
 
 45-3 
 
 23 
 
 9 
 
 Delaware 
 
 17.5 
 
 39-3 
 
 24 
 
 38 
 
 Idaho 
 
 19.6 
 
 45.9 
 
 25 
 
 47 
 
 Iowa 
 
 20.9 
 
 51-2 
 
 26 
 
 
 Nevada 
 
 22.8 
 
 48.0 
 
 27 
 
 43 
 
 Ohio 
 
 24-3 
 
 49-3 
 
 28 
 
 18 
 
 Nebraska 
 
 26.2 
 
 4L5 
 
 29 
 
 2 
 
 Vermont 
 
 26.4 
 
 35** 
 
 3 
 
 
 Colorado 
 
 274 
 
 40.8 
 
 
 3 
 
 Wyoming 
 
 28.6 
 
 35-5 
 
 32 
 
 24 
 
 Washington 
 
 29.9 
 
 43-0 
 
 33 
 
 34 
 
 Maine 
 
 30.2 
 
 45-0 
 
 34 
 
 46 
 
 Utah 
 
 30.2 
 
 49.6 
 
 
 37 
 
 South Dakota 
 
 31-3 
 
 45-7 
 
 96 
 
 29 
 
 California 
 
 32.9 
 
 44.0 
 
 37 
 38 
 
 15 
 17 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 Arizona 
 
 33-4 
 40.8 
 
 40.8 
 41.2 
 
 39 
 
 
 Montana 
 
 41.0 
 
 44.6 
 
 40 
 
 32 
 
 I 
 
 Michigan 
 New Hampshire 
 
 41.1 
 43-3 
 
 44-8 
 33.6 
 
 42 
 
 45 
 
 Illinois 
 
 44.1 
 
 494 
 
 1 Computed from Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 41. 
 
540 Appendix 
 
 TABLE VI. (Concluded). 
 
 Rank according to 
 per cent 
 
 State 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 Unem- 
 ployed 
 
 43 
 44 
 45 
 46 
 
 i 
 
 49 
 50 
 
 16 
 
 27 
 
 25 
 19 
 39 
 7 
 
 21 
 10 
 
 Wisconsin 
 New York 
 North Dakota 
 New Jersey 
 Minnesota 
 Connecticut 
 Massachusetts 
 Rhode Island 
 United States 
 
 48.0 
 50.2 
 52.1 
 52.9 
 
 Si 
 
 65.8 
 65.6 
 
 41.0 
 43-7 
 434 
 41-5 
 46.6 
 38.1 
 41.8 
 39-4 
 
 28.1 
 
 44-3 
 
 TABLE VII. COTTON MILL OPERATIVES, MALE: PER CENT FOREIGN 
 WHITE AND PER CENT UNEMPLOYED, BY STATES, 1900. 
 
 Rank according to 
 per cent 
 
 State 
 
 Pore'gn 
 White 
 
 Unemployed 
 
 Foreign 
 White 
 
 Unem- 
 ployed 
 
 I 
 
 13 
 
 North Carolina 
 
 0.2 
 
 14.8 
 
 2 
 
 7 
 
 South Carolina 
 
 0.2 
 
 II.4 
 
 3 
 
 20 
 
 Alabama 
 
 
 I 7 .6 
 
 4 
 
 9 
 
 Mississippi 
 
 0-3 
 
 II.5 
 
 I 
 
 19 
 15 
 
 Georgia 
 Virginia 
 
 0.4 
 0.9 
 
 I7.I 
 15-4 
 
 7 
 
 i 
 
 Maryland 
 
 1.2 
 
 7-5 
 
 8 
 
 22 
 
 Tennessee 
 
 1.8 
 
 29.6 
 
 9 
 
 10 
 
 Kentucky 
 
 3-1 
 
 13-0 
 
 10 
 
 14 
 
 Texas 
 
 5-3 
 
 15.2 
 
 ii 
 
 23 
 
 Louisiana 
 
 7.2 
 
 34.0 
 
 12 
 
 3 
 
 Indiana 
 
 9.1 
 
 94 
 
 13 
 
 4 
 
 Delaware 
 
 17.8 
 
 II. I 
 
 14 
 
 16 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 
 19.6 
 
 16.1 
 
 15 
 
 8 
 
 Colorado 
 
 23.9 
 
 11.4 
 
 10 
 
 12 
 
 New York 
 
 30-7 
 
 14-3 
 
 II 
 
 17 
 21 
 
 New Jersey 
 Vermont 
 
 36.8 
 48.2 
 
 ~ ** 
 
 16.4 
 21.7 
 
 19 
 
 5 
 
 Connecticut 
 
 60.5 
 
 II. I 
 
 20 
 21 
 
 ii 
 
 18 
 
 Rhode Island 
 Maine 
 
 634 
 65.9 
 
 5 
 
 22 
 
 6 
 
 Massachusetts 
 
 72.3 
 
 Ii. I 
 
 23 
 
 2 
 
 New Hampshire * 
 
 74-5 
 
 9.1 
 
 
 
 United States 
 
 38.4 
 
 13-0 
 
 1 Computed from Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 41. 
 
Appendix 
 
 S4i 
 
 TABLE VIII. PERSONS EMPLOYED IN ALL INDUSTRIES OF MASSA- 
 CHUSETTS, 1888-1908. x 
 
 
 a 
 
 3 
 
 H 
 
 11 
 
 II 
 
 
 | 
 
 1 
 
 I! 
 
 Year 
 
 
 
 *** "5 
 
 Year 
 
 1 
 
 c 
 ' 
 
 o 
 
 
 O 
 
 * 
 
 II 
 
 
 I 
 
 a 
 
 
 li 
 
 1888 
 
 221,307 
 
 169,610 
 
 51,697 
 
 1899 
 
 420,701 
 
 312,054 
 
 108,647 
 
 1889 
 
 293,321 
 
 224,887 
 
 68,434 
 
 1900 
 
 440,363 
 
 322,200 
 
 118,163 
 
 1890 
 
 322,288 
 
 251,107 
 
 71,181 
 
 1901 
 
 456,137 
 
 339,405 
 
 116,732 
 
 1891 
 
 335,919 
 
 260,419 
 
 75,500 
 
 1902 
 
 483,392 
 
 373,385 
 
 110,007 
 
 1892 
 
 352,939 
 
 271,399 
 
 81,540 
 
 1903 
 
 500,348 
 
 377,563 
 
 122,785 
 
 1893 
 
 345,388 
 
 222,370 
 
 123,018 
 
 1904 
 
 493,354 
 
 363,245 
 
 130,109 
 
 1894 
 
 310,167 
 
 206,423 
 
 103,744 
 
 1905 
 
 534,712 
 
 411,869 
 
 122,843 
 
 1895 
 
 351,915 
 
 258,776 
 
 93,139 
 
 1906 
 
 565,472 
 
 448,830 
 
 116,642 
 
 1896 
 
 358,529 
 
 241,363 
 
 117,166 
 
 1907 
 
 607,151 
 
 453,349 
 
 153,802 
 
 1897 
 
 377,399 
 
 272,204 
 
 105,195 
 
 1908 
 
 570,712 
 
 383,588 
 
 187,124 
 
 1898 
 
 386,383 
 
 271,847 
 
 H4,536 
 
 
 
 
 
 TABLE IX. IMMIGRANT BREADWINNERS DESTINED FOR MASSACHU- 
 SETTS, 1 897-1 908. a 
 
 Year 
 
 Number 
 
 Year 
 
 Number 
 
 Year 
 
 Number 
 
 1897 
 
 17,147 
 
 1901 
 
 30,174 
 
 1905 
 
 56,349 
 
 1898 
 
 15,983 
 
 1902 
 
 39,747 
 
 1906 
 
 55,737 
 
 1899 
 
 21,724 
 
 1903 
 
 49,941 
 
 1907 
 
 64,764 
 
 1900 
 
 29,369 
 
 1904 
 
 43,998 
 
 1908 
 
 31,335 
 
 1 Massachusetts Statistics of Manufactures, 1889, pp. 61, 68, 202; 
 1890, pp. 91, 257, 315; 1891, pp. 91, 127, 135; 1892, pp. 33, 47, 399; 
 1893, pp.4i, 53, 3"! 1894, pp. 51, 89, 204; 1896, pp. 28, 70, 168; 1897, 
 pp. 30, 70, 175; 1898, pp. 29, 31, 33, 35, 73, 169; 1901, pp. 70, 80, 82, 87; 
 I 93, PP- 3 3 2 39, A 2 ' Annual Reports of the Bureau of Labor, 
 XXXVII., pp. 285, 288, 316; XXXVIII., pp. 322, 353, 355, 367, 403; 
 XXXIX., pp- 2, 36; XL., p. 2. 
 
 3 Report of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1897, Table IX; 
 1898, p. 26; 1899-1901, Table VII; 1902-1908, Table IX. 
 
542 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE X. INCREASE OR DECREASE ( ) OF THE NUMBER OF BREAD- 
 
 WINNERS, CLASSIFIED BY SEX, NATIVITY, AND OCCUPATION, 
 
 IN THE UNITED STATES, 1890-1900 (THOUSANDS). 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Aggregate 
 
 Native white 
 
 Foreign 
 white 
 
 Colored 
 
 Native 
 parents 
 
 Foreign 
 parents 
 
 All occupations, exclusive 
 of farmers: 
 Both sexes . 
 
 5.304 
 
 2,538 
 
 1,580 
 
 504 
 
 682 
 
 Males 
 
 4,081 
 1,223 
 
 312 
 
 2,014 
 524 
 
 I6 4 
 
 1,232 
 348 
 
 105 
 
 425 
 
 79 
 28 
 
 410 
 272 
 
 15 
 
 Females 
 
 A. Professional service: 
 Both sexes. 
 
 Males 
 
 199 
 "3 
 
 1,423 
 
 IOI 
 63 
 
 587 
 
 65 
 40 
 
 495 
 
 24 
 4 
 
 135 
 
 9 
 6 
 
 206 
 
 178 
 
 28 
 461 
 
 Females 
 
 B. Business and clerical 
 pursuits: * 
 Both sexes 
 
 Males 
 
 1,070 
 353 
 
 3,569 
 
 415 
 172 
 
 1,787 
 
 376 
 119 
 
 980 
 
 IOI 
 
 34 
 341 
 
 Females 
 
 C. All other occupations : 
 Both sexes 
 
 Males 
 
 2,812 
 757 
 
 21 
 
 1,498 
 28 9 
 
 5 
 
 791 
 189 
 
 ~3 
 
 300 
 4i 
 
 II 
 
 9 
 
 2 
 
 Females. 
 
 I. Occupations showing a 
 general decrease in the 
 demand for labor: 
 Both sexes.. 
 
 Males, total 
 
 20 
 
 4 
 i 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 ii 
 
 2 
 
 Brick and tile 
 makers, etc 
 Dairymen. . 
 
 IO 
 
 8 
 
 I 
 
 T 
 
 7 
 
 I 
 
 , . T 
 
 'Occupations at the XII. Census, Table 34, p. cviii., and Table 2, 
 pp. 10 et seq. Compendium of the XI. Census, 1890, Part III, Popula- 
 tion, Table 78, pp. 452 et seq. 
 
 * Agents, bankers, and brokers, officials of banks and companies, 
 manufacturers and officials, etc., boarding- and lodging-house keepers, 
 bookkeepers and accountants, clerks and^copyists, stenographers and 
 typewriters, commercial travelers, salesmen and saleswomen, hotel 
 keepers, merchants and dealers (wholesale), restaurant keepers, saloon 
 keepers, livery-stable keepers, and undertakers. 
 
Appendix 
 
 543 
 
 TABLE X. (Continued). 
 
 
 
 Native 
 
 white 
 
 Foreign 
 
 
 
 
 Native 
 parents 
 
 Foreign 
 parents 
 
 white 
 
 Colored 
 
 All others in this 
 group 3 
 
 2 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 Females: total 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 
 Dairywomen 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 
 II. Occupations in which 
 native white have 
 been displaced by 
 immigrants or their 
 children: 
 Both sexes 
 
 7 
 
 59 
 
 37 
 
 29 
 
 
 Males, total 
 
 22 
 
 72 
 
 34 
 
 15 
 
 I 
 
 Boatmen.canalmen, 
 pilots and sailors 
 
 
 i 
 
 2 
 
 4. 
 
 
 Boot and shoe- 
 makers and re- 
 pairers 
 
 II 
 
 12 
 
 4 
 
 2 
 
 I 
 
 Carpenters anc 
 joiners 
 
 18 
 
 25 
 
 16 
 
 8 
 
 
 Masons (brick anc 
 stone) .... 
 
 
 6 
 
 5 
 
 4 
 
 4 
 
 Tailors 
 
 ^8 
 
 I 
 
 4. 
 
 "35 
 
 
 Woodworkers (not 
 otherwise speci- 
 fied 1 
 
 10 
 
 7 
 
 I 
 
 4, 
 
 
 All others in this 
 
 fiTOUD * 
 
 21 
 
 18 
 
 2 
 
 6 
 
 i 
 
 Females, total 
 
 29 
 
 13 
 
 3 
 
 14 
 
 i 
 
 Cotton mill opera- 
 
 28 
 
 25 
 
 i 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 
 _ . Q 
 
 
 
 
 Seamstresses 
 
 
 y 
 I 
 
 i 
 
 5 
 
 
 Other ^textile mill op 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 2 
 
 2 
 
 i 
 
 All others in thi 
 erouo 5 .. 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 
 'Includes boxmakers (paper), broom and brush makers. 
 
 * Includes distillers and rectifiers, harness and saddle makers and 
 repairers, hat and cap makers, leather curriers and tanners, marble and 
 stone cutters, millers, and plasterers. 
 
 s Includes bleachery and dye works operatives, hucksters and 
 peddlers. 
 
544 Appendix 
 
 TABLE X. (Concluded). 
 
 
 
 Native 
 
 white 
 
 Foreign 
 
 P___- j 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Aggregate 
 
 Native 
 parents 
 
 Foreign 
 parents 
 
 parents 
 
 
 III. Occupations in which 
 immigrants have been 
 displaced by native 
 white: 
 Both sexes 
 
 87Q 
 
 678 
 
 288 
 
 82 
 
 c 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Males, total 
 
 810 
 
 661 
 
 241 
 
 40 
 
 52 
 
 Agri cultural 
 
 68=; 
 
 <;88 
 
 i8d 
 
 IO 
 
 77 6 
 
 All others in agricul- 
 tural pursuits '. . 
 
 Blacksmiths . . 
 
 13 
 16 
 
 16 
 
 7 
 
 TO 
 
 14 
 -~2 
 
 4 
 ~ i 
 
 Clerks and copyists 
 Hostlers 
 
 55 
 
 U 1 
 
 24 
 
 32 
 
 2 
 
 j 
 
 I 
 
 Saw and planing- 
 mill employees.. . 
 All others in this 8 
 
 24 
 6 
 
 H 
 
 3 
 
 *j 
 2 
 
 16 
 j 
 
 Females, total 
 
 69 
 
 17 
 
 47 
 
 42 
 
 47 
 
 Servants and wait- 
 
 69 
 
 16 
 
 47 
 
 41 
 
 47 
 
 Paper- and pulp- 
 
 
 i 
 
 
 I 
 
 
 IV. Occupations showing 
 a general increase in 
 the demand for labor: 
 Both sexes 
 
 2,704 
 
 i,i73 
 
 658 
 
 405 
 
 468 
 
 Males 
 
 2,044 
 
 QI3 
 
 SIQ 
 
 336 
 
 276 
 
 Females 
 
 660 
 
 260 
 
 T-JQ 
 
 oo 
 60 
 
 102 
 
 
 
 
 A oy 
 
 
 
 6 Negroes only. There are no comparative data for other colored 
 agricultural laborers at the XI. Census. 
 
 'Includes gardeners, florists, nurserymen, etc., lumbermen, wood 
 choppers, etc., stock raisers, herders, and drovers. 
 
 Includes brewers and maltsters, potters, telegraph and telephone 
 linemen, trunk and leather-case makers, etc. 
 
TABLE XL NUMBER AND INCREASE OR DECREASE, OF FOREIGN-BORN 
 
 (THOUSAN 
 
 1 1 ' 
 
 Occupations. 
 
 German 
 
 Irish 
 
 English and V 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 Increase 
 (+) 
 or 
 Decrease 
 (-) 
 
 1890 
 
 Z900 
 
 Increase 
 (+) 
 or 
 Decrease 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 Ir 
 D 
 
 Farmers, planters, and 
 overseers 
 
 282.7 
 10.7 
 
 69.6 
 19.9 
 37-9 
 
 26.7 
 95-6 
 
 36.2 
 20.4 
 19.2 
 
 IO.2 
 36.3 
 IS-S 
 154-9 
 
 97.0 
 414.9 
 
 263.7 
 1 8.0 
 
 66.5 
 30-S 
 30.0 
 
 23.0 
 83.6 
 
 39-7 
 18.8 
 Z9.0 
 
 & 
 
 12.0 
 129.6 
 
 8 4 .6 
 421.6 
 
 19.0 
 + 7-3 
 
 3-1 
 + 10.6 
 + 2.1 
 
 3-7 
 
 12.0 
 
 + 3-5 
 1.6 
 .a 
 
 ri:J 
 
 - 3-S 
 -25.3 
 
 12.4 
 
 + 6.7 
 
 93-4 
 2.9 
 25.2 
 
 IO.2 
 14.4 
 
 IS-4 
 46.7 
 
 21.7 
 36.5 
 27-9 
 
 2.3 
 S-8 
 19.6 
 202.4 
 
 35-9 
 245.4 
 
 67.0 
 7-9 
 20.6 
 
 14.9 
 13.9 
 
 15.4 
 41.9 
 
 21.2 
 31.2 
 22.9 
 
 1.7 
 3-8 
 14.6 
 158.9 
 
 30.4 
 247.9 
 
 7II.2 
 
 -26.4 
 + 5.0 
 
 -4-6 
 + 4-7 
 + -5 
 
 .0 
 
 - 4-8 
 
 - .5 
 - 5-3 
 - 5-0 
 
 - .6 
 
 2.O 
 
 - S.o 
 
 -43.5 
 5.5 
 
 + 2.5 
 
 90.5 
 
 7.2 
 
 4.6 
 
 16.6 
 10.3 
 
 17.2 
 
 16.2 
 
 40.4 
 
 21. 1 
 9.1 
 
 56.7 
 
 1.6 
 3.8 
 23.8 
 36.4 
 
 26.7 
 130.7 
 
 57.7 
 9.6 
 
 IS.2 
 14.2 
 19-7 
 
 16.1 
 32.8 
 
 20.5 
 8.3 
 44.9 
 
 9 
 2.3 
 19.6 
 28.3 
 
 21.6 
 
 127.3 
 
 - 
 
 Manufacturers and offi- 
 cials etc 
 
 Merchants and dealers 
 (except wholesale) 
 
 
 
 Bookkeepers, accountants, 
 clerks, and copyists 
 
 Blacksmiths and m a- 
 chinists . 
 
 Steam railroad employees. 
 Miners and quarrymen 
 Saw- and planing-raill em- 
 ployees . . 
 
 Tailors . . 
 
 Textile mill operatives 
 Laborers (not specified) 3 .. . 
 Agricultural laborers and 
 all others in this class. . . 
 All others 
 
 Total 
 
 1.337-7 
 
 1,276.0 
 
 -61.7 
 
 804.7 
 
 487.4 
 
 439.0 
 
 
 
 *XI. Census, Part II., Table 109, p. 484. Reports of the Immigration Cor, 
 Laborers in 1890 include in some agricultural districts agricultural labore 
 
[ALE BREADWINNERS, CLASSIFIED BY NATIONALITY AND OCCUPATION 
 
 IQOO. 1 
 
 Scotch. 
 
 Bohemian. 
 
 Hungarian. 
 
 Italian 
 
 
 
 Increase 
 
 
 
 Increase 
 
 
 
 Increase 
 
 
 
 Imcrease 
 
 JO 
 
 I90O 
 
 or 
 Decrease 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 or 
 Decrease 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 or 
 Decrease 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 or 
 Decrease 
 
 .1 
 
 16.5 
 
 + -4 
 
 14.4 
 
 18.1 
 
 + 3-7 
 
 .8 
 
 1.4 
 
 f .6 
 
 2.2 
 
 4.4 
 
 + 2.2 
 
 .0 
 
 3-3 
 
 -f 2.3 
 
 3 
 
 5 
 
 h * 
 
 .2 
 
 .6 
 
 + -4 
 
 .2 
 
 l.i 
 
 f -9 
 
 9 
 7 
 7 
 
 4.4 
 4.6 
 5-8 
 
 ft? 
 
 + 2.1 
 
 1.2 
 
 i 
 
 2.1 
 
 I.O 
 I.O 
 
 + .9 
 + -6 
 
 1-3 
 
 4 
 
 4 
 
 2.9 
 1.4 
 
 I.O 
 
 + 1.6 
 
 -f- i.o 
 + .6 
 
 7.0 
 5 
 2.3 
 
 16.0 
 
 2.0 
 
 3-8 
 
 -f 9.0 
 
 tii 
 
 7 
 
 5-3 
 12.5 
 
 + .6 
 
 + .2 
 
 .6 
 2.7 
 
 .7 
 3-7 
 
 i;z 
 
 .5 
 '5 
 
 .9 
 1.4 
 
 + '.9 
 
 .8 
 3-3 
 
 1.6 
 
 IO.2 
 
 -f .8 
 + 6.9 
 
 '7 
 : 3 
 
 7.8 
 2.7 
 9-7 
 
 + T '-l 
 2.1 
 
 x.o 
 
 .7 
 9 
 
 1.8 
 .8 
 1.6 
 
 -f .8 
 + .1 
 -f- .7 
 
 3 
 X.3 
 7-3 
 
 ,1 
 
 26.5 
 
 t 5 
 
 +19.2 
 
 4 
 10.3 
 9-7 
 
 1.6 
 
 17.3 
 25.5 
 
 + 7*0 
 4-15-8 
 
 .4 
 .1 
 
 t-7 
 
 r-8 
 
 .4 
 
 I.O 
 
 3-6 
 7-3 
 
 .0 
 I.I 
 
 ~ -5 
 
 1-3 
 3-3 
 
 .2 
 8.2 
 
 .7 
 4.9 
 .4 
 10.0 
 
 - .6 
 + 1.6 
 
 + .2 
 
 + 1.8 
 
 .1 
 x.8 
 3 
 II. 8 
 
 .1 
 3-7 
 I.O 
 
 19.8 
 
 .0 
 
 .2 
 2-3 
 1.2 
 39-0 
 
 5 
 7-8 
 3-9 
 91.8 
 
 -f -3 
 + 5-5 
 
 5 
 
 5 
 
 . 
 
 M 
 
 7.2 
 37.8 
 
 + -7 
 + 5-3 
 
 3-6 
 11.9 
 
 4.8 
 
 19.3 
 
 + 7-4 
 
 .7 
 8.8 
 
 1.4 
 
 23.8 
 
 + -7 
 -fiS.o 
 
 6.5 
 28.2 
 
 12.2 
 76.7 
 
 + 5-7 
 +48.5 
 
 129.9 
 
 II-7 
 
 51-3 
 
 71.4 
 
 20. 1' 
 
 36.S 
 
 88.4 
 
 +5I-9 
 
 114.1 
 
 276.4 
 
 + 162.3 
 
 vol. i, pp. 821-829, Table A. 
 
Appendix 545 
 
 TABLE XII. FOREIGN-BORN ENGAGED IN GAINFUL OCCUPATIONS 
 IN GERMANY, 1900.' 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Thou 
 
 sands 
 
 
 Males 
 
 Females 
 
 Agriculture 
 
 en 
 
 21 
 
 Trade 
 
 77 
 
 IO 
 
 Transportation 
 
 M 
 
 
 Manufactures 
 
 245 
 
 12 
 
 Common labor 
 
 26 
 
 IO 
 
 Professional pursuits 
 
 18 
 
 IO 
 
 Living on income from property 
 
 18 
 
 16 
 
 Servants 
 
 I 
 
 21 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 4.17 
 
 122 
 
 
 
 
 TABLE XIII. FOREIGN-BORN IN GERMANY, BY COUNTRY OF BIRTH 
 (THOUSANDS), 1880-1900.* 
 
 Year 
 
 Total 
 
 Austria- 
 Hungary 
 
 Russia 
 
 Italy 
 
 All other 
 countries 
 
 1880 
 
 419 
 
 150 
 
 57 
 
 8 
 
 204 
 
 1890 
 
 518 
 
 206 
 
 53 
 
 13 
 
 246 
 
 I9OO 
 
 823 
 
 362 
 
 8 9 
 
 62 
 
 310 
 
 Increase 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1880-1900 
 
 404 
 
 212 
 
 32 
 
 54 
 
 1 06 
 
 1 Erganzungsheft zu den Viertelsjahrsheften zur Statistik des Deut- 
 schen Reichs, 1905. Heft I. Die Deutschen im Auslande und die 
 Auslander im Deutschen Reich, p. 40. 
 
 a Ibid. 
 
546 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XIV. FOREIGN-BORN POPULATION FROM THE SCANDINAVIAN COUNTRIES 
 AND FROM SOUTHERN AND EASTERN EUROPE, BY STATES, 1880, 1890, 1900, 
 
 AND I9I0. 1 
 
 States 
 
 From the Scandinavian Countries 
 
 From Southern and Eastern Europe 
 
 1880 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 1910 
 
 1880 
 
 1890 
 
 1900 
 
 1910 
 
 Minnesota.... 
 
 107,768 
 46,046 
 17,869 
 16,685 
 644 
 1,185 
 5" 
 12,755 
 1,524 
 1,942 
 
 215,215 
 72,873 
 65,588 
 46,341 
 6,411 
 3,506 
 2,382 
 16.863 
 21,413 
 7,333 
 
 236,670 
 72,611 
 76,051 
 40,107 
 9.741 
 5.621 
 2,989 
 18,285 
 26,254 
 9,007 
 
 243,899 
 66,586 
 100,654 
 39,592 
 15,513 
 9,775 
 4,078 
 17,826 
 68,228 
 20,153 
 
 7,577 
 2,777 
 6,978 
 7.006 
 191 
 
 100 
 
 78 
 237 
 
 424 
 991 
 
 21,988 
 3,562 
 18,787 
 12,984 
 2,533 
 776 
 1,320 
 789 
 4.949 
 4,005 
 
 30,544 
 6,709 
 33,735 
 16,283 
 6,655 
 1.280 
 2,282 
 1,519 
 7.657 
 4,129 
 
 110,793 
 1,603,071 
 
 76,833 
 34,593 
 65.559 
 47,177 
 23,644 
 7,074 
 9,607 
 10,482 
 44,784 
 22,503 
 
 The Dakotas.. 
 Nebraska 
 Montana 
 Idaho 
 
 Wyoming 
 Utah 
 
 Washington . . 
 
 Total . . , 
 
 206,929 
 233,333 
 
 457,925 
 475,324 
 
 497,336 
 566,973 
 
 586,304 
 664,196 
 
 26,359 
 152,339 
 
 71,693 
 626,677 
 
 342,256 
 4,466,244 
 
 All other 
 
 Total, U. S.. . 
 
 440,262 
 
 933,249 
 
 1,064,309 
 
 1,250,500 
 
 178,698 
 
 698,370 
 
 1,713,864 
 
 4,808,500 
 
 TABLE XV. EMIGRATION FROM THE UNITED KINGDOM, BY DESTINA- 
 TION OF EMIGRANTS, 1840-1909. a 
 
 Year 
 
 & 
 
 I 
 
 
 
 British South 
 Africa 
 
 Australia and 
 New Zealand 
 
 Other Countries 
 
 Tota; 
 
 X84O 
 
 32.2Q7 
 
 40,642 
 
 
 IE SCQ 
 
 T QC8 
 
 OO 74.7 
 
 1841 
 
 38,164 
 
 45.OI7 
 
 
 72 .62 5 
 
 2786 
 
 Il8 5Q2 
 
 1842 
 
 54,123 
 
 6*. 8 52 
 
 
 8.574 
 
 1.875 
 
 128 74.4 
 
 1843 
 
 23,518 
 
 28,77 
 
 
 1.4.78 
 
 *"v)O 
 
 I.88I 
 
 57,212 
 
 1844 
 
 22 ,924 
 
 47,660 
 
 
 2 22Q 
 
 I 877 
 
 7O 686 
 
 1845 
 
 31,803 
 
 58,578 
 
 
 87O 
 
 2 770 
 
 O7 5OI 
 
 1846 
 
 43,439 
 
 82,279 
 
 
 2,74.7 
 
 I 826 
 
 I2O 851 
 
 1847 
 
 109,680 
 
 142,154 
 
 
 4.04.0 
 
 I 4.87 
 
 258 27O 
 
 1848 
 
 31,065 
 
 188,277 
 
 
 27 QO4 
 
 A 887 
 
 *T*/** 
 
 24.8 089 
 
 1849 
 
 41 ,367 
 
 219,450 
 
 
 12 TOT 
 
 6 4.QO 
 
 2OQ 4.08 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Compiled from the United States Census of 1880, vol. i., pp. 492- 
 495; XIII. Census. Population, vol. i., Table 33, pp. 834-838. 
 
 s Compiled from Statistical Abstracts ofthe United Kingdom of Great 
 Britain. Reprint of the Statistical Abstracts for the United Kingdom for 
 1840-1854, p. 84; 14, p. 122; 29, p. 161; 42, p. 239; and 57, p. 363. 
 
Appendix 
 
 TABLE XV. (Continued). 
 
 547 
 
 Year 
 
 
 
 | 
 
 
 1 
 
 a 
 
 
 
 British South 
 Africa 
 
 Australia and 
 New Zealand 
 
 Other Countries 
 
 Total 
 
 1850 
 
 32,961 
 
 223,078 
 
 
 I6.O17 
 
 8 771 
 
 2$O R -in 
 
 1851 
 
 42,605 
 
 267,157 
 
 
 21,5-12 
 
 4.472 
 
 -l-je r\f)f. 
 
 1852 
 
 32,873 
 
 2 44., 26l 
 
 
 87 881 
 
 37/1O 
 
 o5oy 
 
 ifiR "7fiA 
 
 1851 
 
 34*522 
 
 210,885 
 
 
 61 ,401 
 
 >/4y 
 3I2Q 
 
 300,704 
 
 I8S4 
 
 43,76i 
 
 I01,o65 
 
 
 8-1 217 
 
 1 166 
 
 329,937 
 
 1855 
 
 17,966 
 
 101,414 
 
 
 52.1OQ 
 
 3118 
 
 o-^O'^y 
 1 76 8O7 
 
 1856 
 
 16,378 
 
 111,837 
 
 
 44,584 
 
 3.755 
 
 1 76 ^ 5J A. 
 
 1857 
 
 21,001 
 
 126 QO5 
 
 
 61 248 
 
 1 721 
 
 1 /",aO'f 
 212 87 C 
 
 1858 
 
 9,704 
 
 eg, 716 
 
 
 1Q 205 
 
 52^7 
 
 < 1 2,O75 
 III Q*72 
 
 1850 
 
 6,689 
 
 7O.1O1 
 
 
 11 .Oil 
 
 12 427 
 
 i o'y/- 
 I2O A12 
 
 1860 
 
 9,786 
 
 87.5OO 
 
 
 24.1O2 
 
 6,88 1 
 
 128 j.6o 
 
 1861 
 
 12,707 
 
 40,764 
 
 
 21,7l8 
 
 7.56l 
 
 OI 77O 
 
 1862 
 
 15,522 
 
 c8 706 
 
 
 41 84.1 
 
 5141 
 
 121 21/1 
 
 1863 
 
 18,083 
 
 14.6 811 
 
 
 51 O54 
 
 58O8 
 
 221 7^8 
 
 1864 
 
 12,721 
 
 I4.7.O42 
 
 
 4O.Q42 
 
 8.IQ5 
 
 ^^O'/O 
 
 2O8 900 
 
 1865 
 
 17,211 
 
 147,258 
 
 
 17,28l 
 
 "*yo 
 
 8 O4Q 
 
 209 801 
 
 1866 
 
 13,255 
 
 l6l,OOO 
 
 
 24.O07 
 
 6.51O 
 
 204 882 
 
 1867 
 
 12,160 
 
 I26,O5I 
 
 
 I4.O21 
 
 4.748 
 
 I56.O82 
 
 1868 
 
 12,332 
 
 1 08 40O 
 
 
 12 112 
 
 5 Oil 
 
 1 18 187 
 
 1869 
 
 20,921 
 
 14.6.7-17 
 
 
 14 457 
 
 4 185 
 
 1 86 300 
 
 1870 
 
 27,168 
 
 ic -i ,4.66 
 
 
 16,526 
 
 5.151 
 
 202 511 
 
 1871 
 
 24,954 
 
 I 50,788 
 
 
 11,695 
 
 5,114 
 
 102. 751 
 
 1872 
 I8* 7 ! 
 
 24,382 
 29,045; 
 
 161,782 
 166.710 
 
 
 
 15.248 
 25 117 
 
 9,082 
 7 411 
 
 210,494 
 
 228 145 
 
 1874. 
 
 20,728 
 
 1 1 -1,774. 
 
 
 52.581 
 
 IO.l8o 
 
 IQ7 272 
 
 1875 
 
 12,306 
 
 Sl.IQl 
 
 
 14,7 CQ 
 
 12.426 
 
 I4O.675 
 
 1876 
 
 Q,^5 
 
 54,554 
 
 
 12,106 
 
 Il.l84 
 
 IO0.460 
 
 1877 
 
 7,720 
 
 45 48l 
 
 
 1O 1 18 
 
 11,856 
 
 IO5.IQ5 
 
 1878 
 
 10,652 
 
 54 6Q4 
 
 
 l6 47O 
 
 II.O77 
 
 1 12 ,9O2 
 
 1870 
 
 17,052 
 
 Ot'^yt 
 
 OI.8o6 
 
 
 4O.Q5Q 
 
 11,557 
 
 164,274 
 
 1880 
 
 20,902 
 
 166 57O 
 
 
 24 184 
 
 15.886 
 
 227,542 
 
 1881 
 
 21.012 
 
 176 IO4 
 
 
 22 682 
 
 20,^04 
 
 24.1,002 i 
 
 1882 
 
 40,4.4,1 
 
 181 001 
 
 
 17,280 
 
 10,711 
 
 270,166 
 
 188-; 
 
 44,185 
 
 101.57"% 
 
 
 71 ,264 
 
 11,006 
 
 320,118 
 
 1884 
 
 -ilj-id. 
 
 I55.28O 
 
 
 44,255 
 
 11,510 
 
 242,179 
 
 1885 
 
 10 818 
 
 T -17 68? 
 
 
 1O.1Q5 
 
 10,724 
 
 207,644 
 
 1886 
 
 24.745 
 
 152 7IO 
 
 
 41.O76 
 
 12,169 
 
 232,900 
 
 1887 
 
 12 .02 "5 
 
 201,526 
 
 
 14,l8l 
 
 13,753 
 
 281,487 
 
 1888 
 
 14.851 
 
 105,086 
 
 
 31,127 
 
 17,962 
 
 279,928 
 
 1889 
 
 28,269 
 
 168,771 
 
 
 28,294 
 
 28,461 
 
 253,795 
 
Appendix 
 
 TABLE XV. (Concluded). 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 o> 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 11 
 
 1 
 
 0* 
 
 oj"c3 
 
 
 
 Year 
 
 & 3 
 
 1 
 
 "3 
 
 
 
 jl 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 
 21,179 
 
 22,004 
 
 2l8,Il6 
 
 1890 
 
 '5 g 
 
 I ^6*^0 S 
 
 
 ^ ' * * / 7 
 
 19,547 
 
 20,987 
 
 218,507 
 
 1891 
 
 21 26A 
 
 T so'mo 
 
 
 * "*\y^/ 
 
 20,799 
 
 210,042 
 
 T Qft^ 
 
 3' 2 
 
 I4.8.Q4.Q 
 
 
 1 1 ,203 
 
 23,930 
 
 208,814 
 
 IO 93 
 
 T Q.f\A 
 
 T*7 A Cfi 
 
 ^Wff^y 
 
 104 ooi 
 
 
 10,017 
 
 
 156,030 
 
 1094 
 1895 
 
 J. f jnOy 
 
 16,622 
 
 126,502 
 
 20,234 
 
 * **ry * / 
 
 10,567 
 
 1^256 
 
 185,181 
 
 1896 
 
 15,267 
 
 98,921 
 
 24.594 
 
 io,354 
 
 12,789 
 
 161,925 
 
 1897 
 
 15,571 
 
 85,324 
 
 21,109 
 
 12,061 
 
 12,395 
 
 146,460 
 
 1898 
 
 17,640 
 
 80,494 
 
 19.756 
 
 10,693 
 
 12,061 
 
 140,644 
 
 1899 
 
 16,410 
 
 92,482 
 
 14.432 
 
 ",467 
 
 11,571 
 
 146,362 
 
 1900 
 
 i8,433 
 
 102,797 
 
 20,815 
 
 14,922 
 
 11,848 
 
 168,815 
 
 1901 
 
 15,757 
 
 104,195 
 
 23,143 
 
 15.350 
 
 13.270 
 
 171,7^5 
 
 1902 
 
 26,293 
 
 108,498 
 
 43,206 
 
 14,345 
 
 13.320 
 
 205,662 
 
 1903 
 
 59,652 
 
 123,663 
 
 50,206 
 
 12,375 
 
 14,054 
 
 259,950 
 
 1904 
 
 69,681 
 
 146,446 
 
 26,818 
 
 
 14.581 
 
 27L435 
 
 1905 
 
 82,437 
 
 122,370 
 
 26,307 
 
 I5',i39 
 
 15.824 
 
 262,077 
 
 1906 
 
 II4.859 
 
 144,817 
 
 22,804 
 
 I9,33i 
 
 23,326 
 
 325.137 
 
 1907 
 
 151,216 
 
 170,264 
 
 20,925 
 
 24,767 
 
 28,508 
 
 395.680 
 
 1908 
 
 81,321 
 
 96,869 
 
 19.568 
 
 33,569 
 
 31,872 
 
 263,199 
 
 1909 
 
 85,887 
 
 109,700 
 
 22,017 
 
 37.620 
 
 33,537 
 
 288,761 
 
 TABLE XVI. CONGESTION IN DUBLIN: CLASSIFICATION OF TENE- 
 MENTS OF FOUR ROOMS OR LESS, BY NUMBER OF ROOMS 
 AND BY NUMBER OF PERSONS PER TENEMENT, 1901.* 
 
 
 Number of tenements of 
 
 
 i room 
 
 2 rooms 
 
 3 rooms 
 
 4 rooms 
 
 i 
 
 3.278 
 
 702 
 
 172 
 
 IOI 
 
 2 
 
 5.544 
 
 2,234 
 
 779 
 
 597 
 
 3 
 
 4.392 
 
 2,231 
 
 900 
 
 772 
 
 4 
 
 3.384 
 
 2,240 
 
 952 
 
 816 
 
 5 
 
 2,302 
 
 2,022 
 
 825 
 
 818 
 
 6 
 
 1,477 
 
 1.575 
 
 765 
 
 680 
 
 7 
 
 797 
 
 1,205 
 
 620 
 
 562 
 
 8 
 
 362 
 
 773 
 
 433 
 
 422 
 
 9 
 
 US 
 
 367 
 
 238 
 
 320 
 
 10 
 
 47 
 
 1-75 
 
 163 
 
 201 
 
 ii 
 
 13 
 
 62 
 
 74 
 
 9 8 
 
 12 or more 
 
 6 
 
 34 
 
 50 
 
 97 
 
 Total 
 
 21,747 
 
 13,620 
 
 5.971 
 
 5.484 
 
 1 Census of Ireland, 1901. General Report, p. 173, Table 50. 
 
Appendix 
 
 549 
 
 TABLE XVI. (Continued). 
 
 Summary 
 
 Total 
 
 With 4 rooms or less , 
 
 Number of persons per room: 
 
 Not more than one 
 
 Not more than two 
 
 Not more than three , 
 
 More than three.. , 
 
 Number of tenement* 
 59.263 
 46,822 
 
 10.351 
 
 15.039 
 
 9.996 
 
 11,436 
 
 TABLE XVII. "REPRESENTATIVE" HOUSEHOLD EXPENDITURES FOR 
 
 FOOD IN THE IRON DISTRICT OF THE SOUTH, FOR THE PERIOD 
 
 OF ONE WEEK IN 1909.* 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 Persons 
 
 
 Expenditure 
 
 "3 t 
 
 cja 
 
 
 
 per household 
 
 Nutrition 
 
 for food 
 
 kfl 
 
 Nationality 
 
 Income 
 
 
 
 
 Jfe 
 
 
 
 Adults 
 
 Children 
 
 household 
 
 For the 
 week 
 
 Per man 
 per day 
 
 2 
 
 ) 
 
 $10.50 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 21.7 
 
 $6.48 
 
 $0.30 
 
 3 
 4 
 6 
 
 ( South 
 r Italian 
 
 ) 
 
 Q.OO 
 22.OO 
 10.50 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 i 
 
 2 
 
 5 
 
 14.7 
 28.7 
 28.7 
 
 6.1 1 
 8.16 
 10.35 
 
 0.41 
 0.28 
 0.36 
 
 7 
 
 
 16.00 
 
 3 
 
 2 
 
 24-5 
 
 9.10 
 
 0-37 
 
 9 
 
 
 ig.OO 
 
 3 
 
 I 
 
 23-8 
 
 7.65 
 
 0.32 
 
 10 
 ii 
 
 American 
 White 
 
 25.00 
 18.00 
 
 2 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 3 
 
 21.7 
 
 21.7 
 
 7.88 
 7.80 
 
 0.36 
 0.36 
 
 12 
 
 
 12.00 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 12.6 
 
 3-65 
 
 O.29 
 
 13 
 
 
 23.00 
 
 2 
 
 I 
 
 15.6 
 
 9-63 
 
 0.62 
 
 TABLE XVIII. EARNINGS AND EXPENSES IN MASSACHUSETTS, 1800, 
 1830, and 1860.' 
 
 
 1800 
 
 1830 
 
 1860 
 
 Expenses of a family of four 
 
 &12Q 
 
 $4. -II 
 
 $587 
 
 Earnings: 
 Master carpenter 
 
 ^25 
 
 455 
 
 520 
 
 Journeyman carpenter 
 
 266 
 
 JQO 
 
 4.ce 
 
 Master mason 
 
 soo 
 
 soo 
 
 too 
 625 
 
 Journeyman mason 
 
 Z7C 
 
 4^8 
 
 5OO 
 
 Master painter 
 
 ^25 
 
 455 
 
 52O 
 
 Journeyman painter 
 
 26O 
 
 
 455 
 
 Laborer 
 
 
 226 
 
 V5 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Reports of the Immigration Commission, vol. 9, pp. 215-221. 
 3 Third Annual Report of the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of 
 Labor (1871-1872), pp. 514-517. 
 
550 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XIX. AVERAGE INCOME AND EXPENDITURES OF WAGE- 
 EARNERS IN SPECIFIED OCCUPATIONS, IN NEW JERSEY, 1885.' 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Surplus ( -f ) 
 
 
 *< 
 
 J 
 
 1 
 
 1 
 
 *< 
 
 a 
 
 or deficit (-) 
 
 Occupations 
 
 Number c 
 
 famlies 
 
 Average nun 
 in famil3 
 
 G O 
 * 
 
 l! 
 
 '3 o 
 M 
 
 t 
 
 i* 
 
 M 
 
 
 Expenditure 
 family 
 
 
 
 Of head of 
 family 3 
 
 Glass-blowers . 
 
 48 
 
 4-9 
 
 1-3 
 
 $941 
 
 $1,070 
 
 $737 
 
 +$333 
 
 +$204 
 
 Other glass- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 workers . . . 
 
 34 
 
 4.8 
 
 1.6 
 
 693 
 
 813 
 
 654 
 
 + 159 
 
 + 58 
 
 Blacksmiths. . 
 
 ii 
 
 5-9 
 
 1.6 
 
 712 
 
 747 
 
 674 
 
 + 73 
 
 + 19 
 
 Iron- workers. 
 
 15 
 
 4-8 
 
 1-5 
 
 493^ 
 
 573 
 
 538 
 
 
 ~ 45 
 
 Shoemakers. . 
 
 32 
 
 
 1.4 
 
 542 
 
 583 
 
 565 
 
 4~ 18 
 
 - 23 
 
 Carpenters. . . 
 
 12 
 
 5-5 
 
 1-5 
 
 545 
 
 678 
 
 661 
 
 + 17 
 
 - 16 
 
 Machinists. . . 
 
 24 
 
 4-9 
 
 1-5 
 
 558 
 
 629 
 
 619 
 
 + 10 
 
 - 61 
 
 Flax - mill 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 workers .... 
 
 28 
 
 4.9 
 
 1-7 
 
 374 
 
 482 
 
 501 
 
 -19 
 
 - 127 
 
 Silk - mill 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 workers 
 
 34 
 
 4.2 
 
 1-5 
 
 322 
 
 368 
 
 459 
 
 -91 
 
 - 137 
 
 TABLE XX. AVERAGE INCOME AND EXPENDITURES OF UNSKILLED 
 
 LABORERS IN NEW JERSEY, CLASSIFIED BY NATIVITY AND 
 
 SOURCE OF INCOME, 1885.* 
 
 Item 
 
 t Breadwinners in the family 
 
 Father alone 
 
 Father and children 
 
 Native 
 
 English 
 
 Irish 
 
 Native 
 
 English 
 
 Irish 
 
 Number of families 
 
 20 
 
 X 
 
 9 
 
 13 
 
 3 
 
 6 
 
 Earnings of: 
 Father 
 
 $381 
 
 $519 
 
 $2 4 6 
 
 $368 
 222 
 
 $494 
 175 
 
 $249 
 246 
 
 Children 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 $381 
 
 361 
 
 $519 
 567 
 
 $246 
 272 
 
 $590 
 
 578 
 
 $669 
 634 
 
 $495 
 531 
 
 Expenditures 
 
 
 1 Eighth Annual Report of the New Jersey Bureau of Statistics of Labor 
 and Ind. (1885), p. 147. 
 
 a Income of family less expenditures of family. 
 
 3 Earnings of head of family less expenditures of family. 
 
 * Eighth Annual Report of the Bureau of Statistics of New Jersey, 1885, 
 PP- 30-34- 
 
Appendix 
 
 TABLE XX. (Concluded). 
 
 551 
 
 Item 
 
 Breadwinners in the family 
 
 Father alone 
 
 Father and children 
 
 Native 
 
 English 
 
 Irish 
 
 Native 
 
 English 
 
 Irish 
 
 Number of families 
 
 20 
 
 I 
 
 9 
 
 12 
 
 3 
 
 6 
 
 -$36 
 -282 
 
 Surplus (+) or 
 deficit ( ) 
 
 +$20 
 +20 
 
 -48 
 
 -$26 
 -26 
 
 +$12 
 210 
 
 +$35 
 140 
 
 Earnings of father 
 over expenses 
 Surplus (4-) or 
 deficit ( ) .. 
 
 
 TABLE XXI. AVERAGE WAGES AND AVERAGE EXPENSES OF WORKING 
 FAMILIES WITH DEFICITS, IN OHIO, 1885.* 
 
 
 |I 
 
 S, 
 
 0) >> 
 
 Sx 
 
 to one 
 m 
 
 if 
 
 i 
 fc 
 
 0) g 
 
 75 
 
 1*1 
 
 Occupation 
 
 
 
 p 
 
 2 
 
 f 
 
 
 
 a-2 
 
 f 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 < 
 
 
 o< 
 
 Stonecutters . . 
 
 4 
 
 5- 
 
 4-5 
 
 i.i 
 
 $505 
 
 $507 
 
 $2 
 
 3-5 
 
 Machinists 
 
 27 
 
 4-2 
 
 5-3 
 
 0.8 
 
 556 
 
 571 
 
 15 
 
 2.4 
 
 Cabinet- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 makers 
 
 6 
 
 4.5 
 
 4.3 
 
 1.05 
 
 481 
 
 537 
 
 56 
 
 3-5 a 
 
 Iron workers. . 
 
 21 
 
 57 
 
 5-7 
 
 I.O 
 
 679 
 
 745 
 
 66 
 
 5-3 
 
 Wood carvers . . 
 
 5 
 
 5-6 
 
 3-4 
 
 1.6 
 
 659 
 
 772 
 
 113 
 
 2.1* 
 
 Cigar makers... 
 Miners . . . 
 
 20 
 
 cy 
 
 4.8 
 5-8 
 
 3-2 
 4.1 
 
 1-5 
 1.4 
 
 394 
 3<>3 
 
 508 
 
 422 
 
 114 
 119 
 
 4-5 
 2.9 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Eleventh Annual Report of the Ohio Bureau of Labor Statistics (1885), 
 Table 27, p. 117. IX Census, Population Part II., p. 596. 
 3 Cabinet makers and upholsterers. 
 * Woodworkers other than cabinetmakers, carpenters, and joiners. 
 
552 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XXII. ORGANIZED WORKERS AND MALE WHITE BREAD- 
 WINNERS, ENGAGED IN NON-AGRICULTURAL PURSUITS, IN 
 ILLINOIS AND NEW JERSEY, CLASSIFIED BY NATIVITY.* 
 
 
 Illinois, 1886 
 
 New Jersey, 1887 
 
 Nativity 
 
 Breadwinners 
 
 Organized 
 
 Breadwinners 
 
 Organized 
 
 Number: 
 Native 
 Foreign-bora 
 
 423.290 
 308.595 
 
 25.985 
 57.163 
 
 243.093 
 137.385 
 
 24,463 
 26,704 
 
 Total 
 
 Per Cent: 
 
 Native 
 Foreign-bora 
 
 73L885 
 
 57-8 
 42.2 
 
 83,148 
 
 31-3 
 68.7 
 
 380,478 
 
 63-9 
 36-1 
 
 5LI67 
 
 47-8 
 52.2 
 
 Total 
 
 1 00.0 
 
 1 00.0 
 
 1 00.0 
 
 100.0 
 
 TABLE XXIII. MALE LABOR UNION MEMBERSHIP AND IMMIGRATION, 
 NEW YORK STATE, 1897-1910. 
 
 
 H 
 
 in 
 
 
 it 
 
 jl* 
 
 Year 
 
 
 Se 
 
 Year 
 
 i] 
 
 n 
 
 ||* 
 
 
 3| 
 
 fz 
 IJs 
 
 
 33 
 
 its 
 
 
 
 $** 
 
 
 
 H^'** 
 
 1897 
 1898 
 1899 
 
 162,690 
 163,562 
 200,932 
 
 55,871 
 53,310 
 70,740 
 
 1904 
 
 1905 
 1906 
 
 378,859 
 
 370,971 
 386,869 
 
 193,430 
 241,689 
 269,477 
 
 I90O 
 I9OI 
 
 233,553 
 261,523 
 
 99,104 
 106,817 
 
 1907 
 1908 
 
 422,561 
 361,761 
 
 297,300 
 173,022 
 
 1902 
 1903 
 
 313,592 
 380,845 
 
 154,872 
 198,620 
 
 1909 
 1910 
 
 360,319 
 
 453,8oi 
 
 145,036 
 207,021 
 
 1 Fourth Biennial Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics of Illi- 
 nois, 1886, pp. 224-226; Population at XI. Census, Part II, pp. 552-553; 
 ibid., Table 116, p. 586; Tenth Annual Report of the Bureau of Statistics 
 of Labor and Industries of New Jersey, p. 15. 
 
 Annual Report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics of New York State, 
 1910, vol. II., Table 34, p. xlix. 
 
 * Reports of the Commissioner-General ~of Immigration, 1897, p. 
 38; 1898, p. 26; 1899, p. 17; 1900, p. 20; 1901, p. 17; 1902, p. 29; 1903, 
 P- 33J 1904, p. 30; 1905, p. 345 1906, p. 37; 1907, p. 35; 1908, p. 39; 
 1909, P- 575I9IO, p. 55. 
 
Appendix 
 
 SS3 
 
 TABLE XXIV. URBAN POPULATION, MEMBERSHIP OF LABOR UNIONS 
 
 AND PERCENTAGE OF ORGANIZED INDUSTRIAL WAGE-EARNERS 
 
 IN NEW YORK AND KANSAS, 1 900-1909. * 
 
 
 
 Union membership of both sexes 
 
 Vr 
 
 Urban population 
 
 
 
 both sexes a 
 
 
 
 
 
 Number 
 
 Percentage of indus- 
 
 
 
 
 trial wage-earners 3 
 
 
 New York 
 
 Kansas 
 
 New York 
 
 Kansas 
 
 New York 
 
 Kansas 
 
 I9OO 
 
 5,293.1" 
 
 330,903 
 
 245,381 
 
 6,341 
 
 18.3 
 
 57 
 
 I9OI 
 
 5,486,849 
 
 347,191 
 
 276,141 
 
 8,649 
 
 2O.6 
 
 7.8 
 
 I9O2 
 
 5,675,587 
 
 363,479 
 
 329,101 
 
 7,715 
 
 24.6 
 
 7.0 
 
 1903 
 
 5,864,225 
 
 379,767 
 
 395,598 
 
 9,657 
 
 29.6 
 
 8.7 
 
 1904 
 1905 
 
 6,052,963 
 6,241,701 
 
 395,953 
 412,241 
 
 391,676 
 383,226 
 
 12,074 
 
 12,454 
 
 29.3 
 28.6 
 
 10.9 
 
 II.2 
 
 1906 
 
 6,430439 
 
 428,529 
 
 398,494 
 
 12,187 
 
 29.8 
 
 II.O 
 
 1907 
 
 6,619,177 
 
 444,817 
 
 436,792 
 
 13.058 
 
 32.6 
 
 11.8 
 
 1908 
 
 6,807,915 
 
 461 ,005 
 
 372,459 
 
 23,995 
 
 27.8 
 
 21.6 
 
 1909 
 
 6,996,653 
 
 477.293 
 
 372,729 
 
 21,385 
 
 27.9 
 
 19-3 
 
 TABLE XXV. DAILY WAGES IN STEEL COMPANY No. i, 1880-1908.4 
 
 Occupations 
 
 1880 
 
 I88 S 
 
 1890 
 
 1895 
 
 1900 
 
 1903 
 
 1908 
 
 I. Bessemer Depart- 
 ment: 
 
 Laborer 
 
 $1.2-? 
 
 $I.OO 
 
 $I.IO 
 
 $I.IO 
 
 $I.IO 
 
 I.V> 
 
 $1.45 
 
 
 
 
 
 I. OS 
 
 
 2.IO 
 
 2.2O 
 
 Fireman 
 
 1.38 
 
 .89 
 
 
 I.OO 
 
 
 .70 
 
 I.9O 
 
 Carpenter 
 
 
 
 
 1.22 
 
 I. -1C 
 
 .75 
 
 I.9O 
 
 Metal breaker. . . 
 Skull cracker . . . 
 
 2.20 
 
 1.32 
 
 i-55 
 i. 60 
 
 1-33 
 1.18 
 
 1.38 
 
 55 
 55 
 
 1.65 
 
 1.64 
 
 Ashman . 
 
 1.45 
 
 .95 
 
 
 I.OO 
 
 
 .50 
 
 1-55 
 
 1 Annual Report of the New York Bureau of Labor, 1909, p. xxxviii, 
 Table 7; Annual Reports of the Kansas Bureau of Labor, 1900-1909. 
 a Census figures for 1900, estimates for subsequent years. 
 
 * The number of industrial wage-earners at the XII. Census (1900) 
 in New York was 1,337,000, and in Kansas, 110,000. The method of 
 classification and computation is explained in an article by the writer 
 in the Journal of Political Economy, 1911, March and April: "Social- 
 Economic Classes of the Population of the United States. " 
 
 * Report of the Immigration Commission, vol. 8, pp. 448, 449. 
 'Only such occupations have been selected for which comparable 
 
 data are available. 
 
554 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XXV. (Concluded). 
 
 Occupation 
 
 1880 
 
 1885 
 
 1800 
 
 1805 
 
 i poo 
 
 1003 
 
 1908 
 
 
 
 1. 08 
 
 
 
 
 1.30 
 
 I.4O 
 
 
 l.d.5 
 
 
 
 I.OO 
 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.35 
 
 
 
 
 I.IO 
 
 I.OO 
 
 
 1.30 
 
 1-35 
 
 
 
 .68 
 
 75 
 
 I.OO 
 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.35 
 
 II. Blast Furnaces: 
 
 z. io 
 
 1.04 
 
 .00 
 
 .00 
 
 1.20 
 
 1.30 
 
 1.^8 
 
 Engineer . 
 
 i.oo 
 
 1.65 
 
 .60 
 
 .60 
 
 2.2O 
 
 2.50 
 
 2.65 
 
 
 
 
 .15 
 
 1O 
 
 65 
 
 2.IO 
 
 2.25 
 
 Blacksmith 
 Helper 
 
 1.84 
 
 .... 
 
 oy 
 .26 
 .IO 
 
 45 
 .15 
 
 .60 
 25 
 
 2.00 
 
 3 
 
 2.10 
 1.38 
 
 
 1.55 
 
 
 .17 
 
 35 
 
 3 
 
 .84 
 
 2.05 
 
 Carpenter 
 Fireman 
 
 1.55 
 
 1.27 
 
 I.OO 
 
 50 
 .17 
 
 -45 
 .30 
 
 .60 
 5 
 
 .80 
 .75 
 
 1.90 
 
 1.85 
 
 Hot-stove tender 
 
 
 
 .26 
 
 .45 
 
 .60 
 
 .70 
 
 ,80 
 
 
 
 
 .IO 
 
 .OO 
 
 .20 
 
 55 
 
 .60 
 
 
 
 
 .15 
 
 .15 
 
 5 
 
 .50 
 
 .60 
 
 Coke fillers 
 Cinder man 
 
 1-55 
 1.55 
 
 1. 15 
 
 25 
 .20 
 
 .OO 
 .26 
 
 .40 
 
 50 
 
 .45 
 
 .60 
 
 55 
 
 Fillers 
 
 I.5O 
 
 I.I5 
 
 .25 
 
 35 
 
 44 
 
 .40 
 
 50 
 
 
 
 
 .OO 
 
 .20 
 
 32 
 
 .15 
 
 45 
 
 
 
 
 .00 
 
 1. 20 
 
 .32 
 
 3O 
 
 38 
 
 III. Mechanical De- 
 partment: 
 
 Brick mason: 
 Minimum 
 
 1.85 
 
 1.57 
 
 1.05 
 
 1. 80 
 
 1. 80 
 
 2.25 
 
 2.47 
 
 Maximum 
 Patternmaker: . 
 Minimum 
 Maximum 
 Blacksmith: 
 Minimum 
 Maximum 
 Boilermaker: 
 Minimum 
 
 2-45 
 
 1-55 
 2.50 
 
 1.65 
 2.70 
 
 I 60 
 
 3-42 
 
 1-54 
 2-43 
 
 i 62 
 
 2.50 
 1-35 
 
 2. 2O 
 
 I 75 
 
 3-00 
 
 1.62 
 
 2.58 
 
 I 65 
 
 3-65 
 
 2.10 
 2.70 
 
 I 6O 
 
 3-24 
 
 1.48 
 3-00 
 
 i-43 
 2.92 
 
 i 48 
 
 3-60 
 
 1-55 
 3-25 
 
 1-57 
 3-25 
 
 1.62 
 
 Maximum 
 Roofer: 
 Minimum 
 
 2-75 
 I 5O 
 
 2.25 
 i ii 
 
 */> 
 2.50 
 
 I 6O 
 
 *-v3 
 2.47 
 
 I "?J. 
 
 2.85 
 
 I 55 
 
 2.67 
 i 10 
 
 2-95 
 
 I 45 
 
 Maximum 
 Carpenter: 
 Minimum 
 Maximum... . . 
 Painter: 
 Minimum 
 
 2.OO 
 
 1.60 
 2.50 
 
 1. 20 
 
 ^o 1 
 
 2.50 
 
 1. 60 
 1.80 
 
 2.70 
 
 t "O e t 
 
 2.50 
 
 2.OO 
 2. 2O 
 
 *OO 
 2.75 
 
 i-55 
 2.40 
 
 *jp* 
 
 2.40 
 
 1.29 
 2-37 
 
 1.98 
 
 2.65 
 1.41 
 
 2.60 
 
 2.17 
 
 Maximum 
 
 2.IO 
 
 
 
 
 
 2 25 
 
 2.47 
 
 Mason (helper) : 
 Minimum 
 Maximum 
 
 I.IO 
 1.30 
 
 70 
 1.48 
 
 .... 
 
 I.I5 
 
 1-35 
 
 i.iS 
 1.40 
 
 I.IO 
 1-35 
 
 1.20 
 1.48 
 
Appendix 555 
 
 TABLE XXVI. PER CENT OF MACHINE- MINED BITUMINOUS COAL 
 AND PER CENT RATIO OF FOREIGN-BORN FROM SOUTHERN AND 
 EASTERN EUROPE FOR EACH OF THE PRINCIPAL COAL-PRODUCING 
 STATES, 1900 and 1910.* 
 
 State 
 
 Mined by machinery 
 
 Ratio of Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans to 
 total population 3 
 
 Per cent of min- 
 ers of S. and . 
 European par- 
 entage 
 
 1910 
 
 1900 
 
 1910 
 
 1900 
 
 1900 
 
 Ohio 
 
 84.44 
 64.03 
 48.87 
 45-51 
 45-37 
 38.63 
 
 46.53 
 43-91 
 27.36 
 
 33-65 
 15.09 
 
 19-73 
 
 5-5 
 0-3 
 1.8 
 10.9 
 
 1.2 
 
 7-9 
 
 1-5 
 
 O.I 
 
 0.5 
 4-9 
 0.6 
 3-0 
 
 9.0 
 0-5 
 5-5 
 36.0 
 
 9-5 
 22.0 
 
 Kentucky. .. 
 
 Indiana 
 
 Pennsylvania 
 West Virginia 
 Illinois 
 
 
 TABLE XXVII. PER CENT OF MINERS OF SOUTHERN AND EASTERN 
 
 EUROPEAN PARENTAGE,* LIVES LOST PER MILLION TONS, AND 
 
 PER 1,000 EMPLOYEES, IN BITUMINOUS COAL MINES. * 
 
 State 
 
 Per cent of miners of 
 S. and E. European 
 parentage. 1900 
 
 Fatal accidents per 
 i, ooo employees, 
 1889-1908 
 
 Lives lost per 
 million tons, 
 1866-1908 
 
 Pennsylvania. . . . 
 Illinois 
 
 36.0S 
 
 22 .0 
 
 2.71 
 2.33 
 
 3-83 
 
 3-94 
 
 Oklahoma 
 West Virginia 
 Chio 
 
 I4.O 
 
 9-5 
 o.o 
 
 5.07 
 4.64 
 2.14 
 
 I3 4l 
 
 3-95 
 
 
 6.0 
 
 2.15 
 
 5.22 
 
 
 5.5 
 
 2.32 
 
 3.73 
 
 
 2.O 
 
 455 
 
 7.27 
 
 \laryland 
 
 IS 
 
 1.77 
 
 1.96 
 
 Tennessee 
 
 I.O 
 
 4.38 
 
 9.04 
 
 Kentucky 
 
 0.5 
 
 1. 60 
 
 3-34 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 U. S. Geological Survey, Production of Coal, 1910, p. 51. These six 
 States produced 90 per cent of the total output of machine-mined coal in 
 the United States for 1900-1909, and 80 per cent of the total output of 
 bituminous coal for 1910. 
 
 * Advance information issued to the "press by the [Director of the 
 Census. 
 
 J Computed from XII. Census Report on Occupations, Table 41. 
 
 * Bureau of Labor Bulletin No. go, Table XXIX, pp. 452, 6/1. 
 s Includes both bituminous and anthracite mines. 
 
556 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XXVIII. NUMBER OF EMPLOYEES AND FATAL ACCIDENT 
 RATES IN THE ANTHRACITE MINES OF PENNSYLVANIA, 1870-1909.' 
 
 
 
 b 
 
 L 
 
 
 
 Is 
 
 1 
 
 
 w/ 3 > 
 
 S& 
 
 SB g^ 
 
 
 89 1? 
 
 0) 
 
 m o 
 
 
 s'S 
 
 g l 
 
 l 
 
 
 8-g 
 
 2 
 
 'S* > 'S 
 
 Years 
 
 i 
 
 3s 
 
 
 Years 
 
 jo gJ 
 
 ^ a 
 
 O o 3 
 
 
 go 
 
 I* 
 
 g2 
 
 
 aj 
 
 
 
 ||1 
 
 
 W^, 
 
 3q 
 
 3* 
 
 
 w*^ 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 M " 
 
 i 
 
 
 
 i2 M " 
 
 I" 
 
 1870 
 
 36 
 
 5-93 
 
 14.89 
 
 1890 
 
 120 
 
 3-15 
 
 8.4O 
 
 1871 
 
 37 
 
 5-60 
 
 13.52 
 
 1891 
 
 123 
 
 3-47 
 
 8.61 
 
 1872 
 
 45 
 
 4.98 
 
 14.32 
 
 1892 
 
 130 
 
 3-21 
 
 8.16 
 
 1873 
 
 48 
 
 5.48 
 
 12.57 
 
 1893 
 
 138 
 
 3.30 
 
 8.63 
 
 1874 
 
 53 
 
 4.33 
 
 11.59 
 
 1894 
 
 I4O 
 
 3-19 
 
 8.75 
 
 1875 
 
 70 
 
 3-40 
 
 10.17 
 
 1895 
 
 144 
 
 2.93 
 
 7-39 
 
 1876 
 
 70 
 
 3-24 
 
 9.73 
 
 1896 
 
 150 
 
 3-34 
 
 9-32 
 
 1877 
 
 67 
 
 2.90 
 
 7.85 
 
 I8 97 
 
 150 
 
 2.83 
 
 8.04 
 
 1878 
 
 64 
 
 2.92 
 
 8.95 
 
 1898 
 
 142 
 
 2.89 
 
 7.78 
 
 1879 
 
 69 
 
 3-81 
 
 8.44 
 
 1899 
 
 141 
 
 3.28 
 
 7.62 
 
 1880 
 1881 
 
 11 
 
 2-75 
 
 3-59 
 
 7.22 
 7.98 
 
 1900 
 1901 
 
 144 
 148 
 
 2.86 
 3-47 
 
 7.16 
 7-65 
 
 1882 
 
 82 
 
 3-54 
 
 8.30 
 
 1902 
 
 148 
 
 2.03 
 
 7.26 
 
 1883 
 1884 
 
 91 
 
 IOI 
 
 3-53 
 3-28 
 
 8.56 
 9.10 
 
 1903 
 1904 
 
 152 
 
 161 
 
 3-41 
 3.69 
 
 6.89 
 8.08 
 
 1885 
 
 100 
 
 3.31 
 
 8.68 
 
 1905 
 
 168 
 
 3.83 
 
 8.19 
 
 1886 
 
 103 
 
 2.71 
 
 7.16 
 
 1906 
 
 166 
 
 3-35 
 
 7.72 
 
 1887 
 
 107 
 
 2.97 
 
 7-50 
 
 1907 
 
 169 
 
 4.20 
 
 8.23 
 
 1888 
 
 122 
 
 2.98 
 
 7.81 
 
 1908 
 
 175 
 
 3-88 
 
 8.12 
 
 1889 
 
 120 
 
 3-32 
 
 9.09 
 
 1909 
 
 171 
 
 3-31 
 
 7.07 
 
 Report of the Pennsylvania Department of Mines, 1909, Part I, 
 Table L., p. 57. 
 
Appendix 
 
 557 
 
 TABLE XXIX. NUMBER OF FATAL ACCIDENTS AND RATIO PER 1000 
 EMPLOYEES ON RAILROADS AND IN COAL MINES, 1889-1908. 
 
 Number 
 
 Ratio per 1000 employees 
 
 
 I 
 
 !! 
 
 1 
 
 is mines, 
 Canada 
 
 S 
 1 
 
 11 
 
 1 
 
 1 
 
 s mines, 
 Canada 
 
 Years 
 
 1 
 
 H 
 
 1 
 
 jl 
 
 tf 
 
 II 
 
 1 
 
 il 
 
 
 J 
 
 <3 <u 
 
 
 
 id 
 
 J 
 
 Sgl 
 
 J 
 
 IN 
 
 
 S 
 
 
 3 
 
 & 
 
 * 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 1889 
 
 1,179 
 
 1,972 
 
 397 
 
 681 
 
 8.55 
 
 2.80 
 
 3-31 
 
 245 
 
 1890 
 1891 
 
 i,459 
 ,533 
 
 2,451 
 2,660 
 
 378 
 428 
 
 852 
 952 
 
 9.61 
 
 3.27 
 
 3-39 
 
 3-15 
 347 
 
 2.8 4 
 2.92 
 
 1892 
 
 ,503 
 
 2,554 
 
 418 
 
 880 
 
 8.85 
 
 
 3.21 
 
 2.57 
 
 1893 
 
 ,567 
 
 2,727 
 
 456 
 
 969 
 
 8.70 
 
 3-13 
 
 3-30 
 
 2.53 
 
 1894 
 
 ,029 
 
 1,823 
 
 446 
 
 956 
 
 6.41 
 
 2-33 
 
 3-19 
 
 2.44 
 
 1895 
 
 ,017 
 
 l,8n 
 
 421 
 
 ,053 
 
 645 
 
 2.31 
 
 2-93 
 
 2.62 
 
 1896 
 
 ,073 
 
 1,861 
 
 502 
 
 ,123 
 
 6-59 
 
 2.25 
 
 3-34 
 
 2.74 
 
 1897 
 
 976 
 
 1,693 
 
 "423 
 
 947 
 
 6.08 
 
 2.06 
 
 2.83 
 
 2.32 
 
 1898 
 
 ,141 
 
 1,958 
 
 411 
 
 ,049 
 
 6.67 
 
 2.24 
 
 2.89 
 
 2.59 
 
 1899 
 
 ,155 
 
 2,210 
 
 461 
 
 ,249 
 
 645 
 
 2.38 
 
 3-28 
 
 2.97 
 
 1900 
 
 1,396 
 
 2,550 
 
 411 
 
 ,501 
 
 7-30 
 
 2.51 
 
 2.86 
 
 3-25 
 
 1901 
 
 1,537 
 
 2,675 
 
 513 
 
 ,579 
 
 7-35 
 
 2.50 
 
 347 
 
 3-21 
 
 1902 
 
 1,670 
 
 2,969 
 
 300 
 
 ,837 
 
 7.40 
 
 249 
 
 2.03 
 
 347 
 
 1903 
 
 2,061 
 
 3,6o6 
 
 518 
 
 ,815 
 
 8.13 
 
 2.75 
 
 341 
 
 3.16 
 
 1904 
 
 2,115 
 
 3,632 
 
 595 
 
 2,018 
 
 8.33 
 
 2.80 
 
 3-69 
 
 3-33 
 
 1905 
 
 1,993 
 
 3,361 
 
 644 
 
 2,178 
 
 7-51 
 
 243 
 
 3-83 
 
 340 
 
 1906 
 
 2,302 
 
 3,929 
 
 
 2,093 
 
 8.08 
 
 2.58 
 
 3-35 
 
 3.19 
 
 1907 
 
 2,542 
 
 4,534 
 
 708 
 
 2,838 
 
 8.00 
 
 2.71 
 
 4.19 
 
 4-15 
 
 1908 
 
 1,845 
 
 3405 
 
 678 
 
 2,723 
 
 6.67 
 
 2-37 
 
 3-89 
 
 3-82 
 
 1 Figures for 1891-1908 from U. S. Statistical Abstract, 1910, Tables 
 180 and 181, p. 284, also Table 168, p. 265; U. S. Bureau of Labor Bul- 
 letin go, Table xxiv., pp. 655-659; Bulletin 32, p. 8. 
 
558 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XXX. ARRIVAL AND DEPARTURE OF ALIENS (THOUSANDS), 
 
 I9O8-I92O. 1 
 
 
 
 All Aliens 
 
 
 
 
 Excess of 
 immigra- 
 
 Fiscal year 
 ended June 30. 
 
 Admitted 
 
 Departed 
 
 Net 
 Increase 
 
 Immi- 
 grants 
 
 grants 
 
 tion over 
 emigra- 
 tion 
 
 1008 . , 
 
 925 
 
 7 1 5 
 
 2IO 
 
 783 
 
 395 
 
 388 
 
 IOOO 
 
 944 
 
 400 
 
 544 
 
 752 
 
 223 
 
 529 
 
 IQIO. . . 
 
 1,198 
 
 380 
 
 818 
 
 1,042 
 
 202 
 
 840 
 
 IQII 
 
 1,030 
 
 518 
 
 512 
 
 879 
 
 295 
 
 584 
 
 loia 
 
 1,017 
 
 615 
 
 402 
 
 838 
 
 333 
 
 505 
 
 IQM. . 
 
 1,427 
 
 612 
 
 8i5 
 
 1,198 
 
 308 
 
 890 
 
 IQI4. 
 
 I t43 
 
 634 
 
 709 
 
 1,218 
 
 303 
 
 915 
 
 IQI S 
 
 474 
 
 384 
 
 50 
 
 327 
 
 204 
 
 123 
 
 IQl6. . . 
 
 367 
 
 241 
 
 126 
 
 299 
 
 130 
 
 169 
 
 1017 ., 
 
 362 
 
 146 
 
 216 
 
 295 
 
 66 
 
 229 
 
 IQl8. .. 
 
 212 
 
 193 
 
 19 
 
 III 
 
 95 
 
 16 
 
 IQIQ. .. 
 
 237 
 
 216 
 
 21 
 
 141 
 
 124 
 
 17 
 
 IQ2O 
 
 622 
 
 428 
 
 1 04 
 
 41O 
 
 288 
 
 142 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Total... 
 
 10,179 
 
 5,483 
 
 4,695 
 
 8,312 
 
 2,970 
 
 5,342 
 
 1 Annual Report of the Commissioner-General of Immigration, 1920, Table XVI A, 
 p. 191. 
 
Appendix 
 
 559 
 
 TABLE XXXI. IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION OF BREADWINNERS,* 
 FISCAL YEARS 1915-1919.' 
 
 Year Ended 
 June 30 
 
 Admitted 
 
 Departed 
 
 Immigrant 
 aliens 
 
 Non-immigrant 
 aliens 
 
 Emigrant 
 aliens 
 
 Non-emigrant 
 aliens 
 
 IQ.I5.. 
 
 209,760 
 194,060 
 190,985 
 
 65,655 
 82,818 
 
 72,361 
 45,671 
 46,758 
 81,788 
 73,388 
 
 175,609 
 112,376 
 50,353 
 69,483 
 101,293 
 
 136,221 
 
 75,244 
 53,127 
 80,967 
 70,432 
 
 I0l6.., 
 
 IQI7... 
 
 IQl8 . 
 
 1919 
 
 TABLE XXXII COMPARISON OF PERSONS SEEKING WORK AND 
 WORKERS CALLED FOR BY EMPLOYERS AT PUBLIC EMPLOYMENT 
 OFFICES IN THE STATE OF NEW YORK: NUMBER OF WORKERS 
 REGISTERED FOR EACH ONE HUNDRED PLACES OPEN, 1916-18.' 
 
 MONTH 
 
 1916 
 
 1917 
 
 1918 
 
 Tanuarv . 
 
 1^6 2 
 
 88 I 
 
 QI O 
 
 February 
 
 121 .6 
 
 84. 4. 
 
 84. * 
 
 March . 
 
 07 I 
 
 78 8 
 
 68 2 
 
 April 
 
 7-1 C 
 
 81 7 
 
 61 o 
 
 May 
 
 7V4 
 
 83.7 
 
 5V 8 
 
 June 
 
 78.5 
 
 70 4. 
 
 so s 
 
 July. 
 
 67 I 
 
 7C Q 
 
 6O 7 
 
 August 
 
 7C Q 
 
 7-1.0 
 
 c-i 7 
 
 September . 
 
 74. ^ 
 
 75 6 
 
 C2 7 
 
 October 
 
 72.1 
 
 80.7 
 
 47.1 
 
 
 74. 8 
 
 01 "^ 
 
 CQ -J 
 
 December 
 
 77.2 
 
 85.8 
 
 71 .7 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 All aliens, exclusive of "persons without occupation, mostly women 
 and children." 
 
 2 Annual Reports of the Commissioner General of Immigration, 1915- 
 1919, Table VI.: occupations of aliens admitted and departed. 
 
 8 Compiled from The Labor Market Bulletin, published monthly by 
 the Bureau of Statistics and Information of the New York State 
 Industrial Commission. Beginning with July, 1018, the reports on 
 which the above table is based comprise the operations of the Employ- 
 ment Bureaus of the New York State Industrial Commission and of 
 the U. S. Employment Service in New York State. Previous to that 
 date, the reports related only to the Employment Bureaus of the New 
 York State Industrial Commission. 
 
560 
 
 Appendix 
 
 TABLE XXXIII. EXPORTS OF PRINCIPAL BREADSTUFFS, OTHER THAN 
 WHEAT, FROM THE UNITED STATES, 
 
 A rtirl*. 
 
 July ist to 
 
 June 30th 
 
 T_ ______ 
 
 
 1910-1914 
 
 1914-1918 
 
 
 Barley bushels 
 
 Thousands 
 35,166 
 
 Thousands 
 106,895 
 
 Percent 
 2O4 
 
 Rye bushels . . 
 
 4.O54 
 
 52.127 
 
 I IQI 
 
 Rye flour, barrels 
 
 24 
 
 I.I4O 
 
 4.65O 
 
 Corn meal barrels -. . 
 
 1,668 
 
 1.417 
 
 IQC 
 
 Oatmeal, pounds 
 
 106,061 
 
 580,607 
 
 447 
 
 Rice pounds .... 
 
 85.107 
 
 574.87Q 
 
 571 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 Statistical Abstract of United States t 1918, pp. 477-478 (computed). 
 
INDEX 
 
 AGRICULTURAL LABORERS, Dis- 
 placement: by machinery, 109; 
 Earnings: compared with earn- 
 ings in similar non-agricultural 
 occupations, in; Wages: no 
 
 AGRICULTURAL POPULATION, lim- 
 its to further growth of, 112; 
 movement to the city, 491, 506, 
 5<>7 
 
 AGRICULTURE, 103-113, (See also: 
 Rural Depopulation); Centrali- 
 zation of industry: effect upon 
 farming, 107; Demand: for 
 labor in a. and in industry, 7, 
 104; Differentiation of manu- 
 facturing: from a., 106, 107; 
 Irish Immigrants: reluctance 
 towards a., 66; Machiipry: 108; 
 Wages: low, no; of agricul- 
 tural and other unskilled labor- 
 ers, in 
 
 ALIENS, arrival and departure of, 
 1908-1920, 558 
 
 AN'THRACITE COAL, (See: Coal 
 Mines, Anthracite) 
 
 ANTHRACITE COAL STRIKE COM- 
 MISSION, award of the, 456 
 
 APARTMENT HOUSES, increase, 282 
 
 ARISTOCRACY OF LABOR, English- 
 speaking, created by immigra- 
 tion, 9, 161, 163, 164, 394 
 
 ASSIMILATION, English language: 
 ability to speak, 58 ; Problem of: 
 42, 75; Recent immigrants: 77 
 
 B 
 
 BASTABLE, C. P., 218, 219 
 
 BERGER, VICTOR L., 394 
 
 BEVERIDGE, W. H., 114, 121, 123, 
 124, 126, 522; (See also: Un- 
 employment) 
 
 BING, ALEXANDER M., 500, 501, 
 505 
 
 BIRDS OF PASSAGE, 74; by race, 
 75 
 
 BIRTH RATE, (See: Race Suicide) 
 
 BITUMINOUS COAL, (See: Coal, 
 Bituminous) 
 
 BITUMINOUS COAL MINES, (See: 
 Coal Mines, Bituminous) 
 
 BOARDERS AND LODGERS, Earn- 
 ings: of head of family, 253; 
 Old immigration: per cent of 
 families keeping b. a. 1. among 
 the races of the, 253; Rent: and 
 b. a. 1., 254; Statistics: of the 
 Immigration Commission unre- 
 liable, 251, 252 
 
 BOSTON, 25, 65, 241, 242, 356, 363; 
 Home ownership: 1845-1900, 
 277; Housing: number of fami- 
 lies per house, 1853-1900, 242; 
 Tenancy: 1790, 1845, 1890, and 
 1900, 276; Tenement houses: 
 1855 and 1900, 241; unsanitary 
 in the '70*8, 241, 242 
 
 BREADWINNERS, English: number, 
 1890 and 1900, 1 66; in selected 
 occupations, 1 890-1 900, 1 68 ; 
 German: number, 1890 and 
 1900, 1 66; in selected occupa- 
 tions, 170; Increase or decrease: 
 by sex, nativity, and occupa- 
 tion, 1890-1900, 141; Irish: 
 number, 1890 and 1900, 166; 
 in selected occupations, 169; 
 Welsh: number, 1890 and 1900, 
 1 66; in selected occupations, 
 1 68; (See also: Foreign-born; 
 Immigration) 
 
 BRITISH COLONIES, British immi- 
 gration to, encouraged by colo- 
 nial governments, 210 
 
 BRITISH EMIGRATION, decline of, 
 effect of home conditions, 173 
 
 BRITISH IMMIGRATION, encouraged 
 by colonial governments, 210 
 
 BUDGETS, (See: Family Budgets) 
 
 BURNETT, JOHN L., 43 
 
562 
 
 Index 
 
 CANADA, (See: Emigration, Amer- 
 ican farmers) 
 
 CAPITAL, emigration of, 491, 492, 
 510; immigration of, 522-523 
 
 CARLTON, FRANK TRACY, 61, 307, 
 308, 318, 330, 349, 35i 
 
 CASTE PREJUDICE, against the 
 immigrant, outgrowth of occu- 
 pational stratification, 424 
 
 CHAPIN, ROBERT COIT, 240, 258, 
 260, 261 
 
 CHILD LABOR, 107, 318-324; Cot- 
 ton mills: children under 14 in 
 Northern and Southern, 321; 
 children under 14 in principal 
 States, 321; Decrease: of, con- 
 temporaneous with the increase 
 of immigration, 318; in States 
 with a large immigrant popula- 
 tion, 26; Defenders: of, in the 
 South, 321; Foreign-born: per 
 cent of, and per cent of children 
 under 16 employed in factories 
 in leading States, 319; Increase, 
 during the World War, 508, 509 ; 
 Parent nativity: of children, 10 
 to 15 years, in manufactures, by 
 geographical divisions, 320; 
 Shoe factories: c. 1. in, of rural 
 Missouri, 322; South: more 
 frequent in the, than in States 
 with large immigrant popula- 
 tion, 319; Substitute for immi- 
 gration, 26, 321, 490, 527 
 
 CIVIL WAR, cost of living, 307; 
 labor organizations, 330; wages, 
 307-308 
 
 CLAGHORN, KATE H., 65, 66, 357 
 
 CLOTHING INDUSTRY, 265-267 ; 
 (See also: Family Budgets; 
 Farmhouse Labor; Garment 
 Workers); Growth: of, since 
 1890, 369; Hours of labor: in 
 middle of nineteenth century, 
 363; Strikes: compared with 
 average for all industries, 1887- 
 !905, 373J Wages, real: of 
 women in the past lower than 
 to-day, 364, 365 
 
 CLOTHING WORKERS, (See: Gar- 
 ment Workers) 
 
 COAL, Demand: fluctuations in 
 the, for, 432, 433, 434; Pro- 
 duction: per capita, 105; by 
 
 months, 433; and population, 
 419; in the U. S., 1880-1910, 
 416-417 
 
 COAL, BITUMINOUS, machine 
 mined, per cent of, and per- 
 centage of miners from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe, by States, 
 
 429, 555 
 
 COAL MINERS, 414-457; Unem- 
 ployed: and per cent foreign 
 white, by States, 538; Westward 
 movement: caused by the open- 
 ing of new mining fields, 418 
 
 COAL MINERS, BITUMINOUS, Wage 
 scale: in Pennsylvania, 1895- 
 
 1908, 441 ; Wages: by race and 
 locality, 442 
 
 COAL MINES, (See also: Coal; Coal 
 Miners ; Fatal Accidents ; Strikes ; 
 Work Accidents) ; Competition: 
 of unorganized native American 
 mine workers, 447; Fatal acci- 
 dents: in the U. S. and foreign 
 countries, 469; Unemployment: 
 part-time employment in lieu 
 
 of, 434 
 
 COAL MINES, ANTHRACITE, (See 
 also: Anthracite Coal Strike 
 Commission; Strikes); Fatal 
 accident rate: 1870-1909, 479, 
 556; Miners' unions: short 
 lived prior to the New Immigra- 
 tion, 455; Pro duction: of, 1870- 
 
 1909, 4371 Wage-earners: num- 
 ber in, 1870-1909, 437 
 
 COAL MINES, BITUMINOUS, Days 
 worked: average number of, 
 and variation of the number of 
 immigrant miners and laborers 
 in Pennsylvania, 140, 141; 
 Employees: number, 1880-1907, 
 420; Fatal accident rate: by 
 nativity and causes, 474; by 
 nativity and length of experi- 
 ence, 477; compared with rail- 
 roads, 485, 557; variation of the 
 percentage of miners of Slavic 
 and Italian parentage, 472, 527; 
 Labor organizations, 445; Un- 
 employment: ratio of, and per- 
 centage of foreign-born miners, 
 134"; Wages, union scale of, 
 1898-1908, 440 
 
 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, (See : 
 Labor Organizations, World 
 War) 
 
Index 
 
 563 
 
 COMMISSARY STORE, (See: Com- 
 pany Store) 
 
 COMMONS, JOHN R., 62, 114, 289, 
 291, 298, 302, 307, 362, 454, 518 
 
 COMPANY HOUSES, 247, 248 
 
 COMPANY STORE, 272; Movement 
 against: 1849-1897,444; in the 
 South, 443 
 
 COMPETITION, IMMIGRANT, new 
 immigrants not working for less 
 pay than natives or older im- 
 migrants, 401 
 
 CONGESTION, (See also: Housing 
 Conditions; Tenement Houses); 
 Boston: number of families per 
 house, 1853-1900, 242; Dublin: 
 c. in, 520; Effect: upon cost of 
 living and wages, 240; Failure 
 of the community: to provide 
 safeguards against, 239; In- 
 dustrial causes, 235; Ireland: 
 c. in, 244; New York City: 229- 
 241; Old Immigration: 65; 
 Race: not a factor, 237; Rear 
 tenements, 233 
 
 CONTRACT LABORERS, importa- 
 tion of, infrequent, 99, 394, 524; 
 during the World War, 498-499, 
 
 530 
 
 COST OF LIVING, 240, 521, (See 
 also: Wages and the Cost of 
 Living) 
 
 COTTON MILLS, 375-383, (See also: 
 Child Labor); Earnings: of 
 operatives, by sex and age, by 
 principal States, 387; Hours of 
 labor, 31 5; Strikes: much above 
 the average in duration, 379; 
 Unemployed: and foreign-born, 
 136, 540 
 
 CRAFT UNIONS, (See: Labor Or- 
 ganizations) 
 
 CRIME, 353, 358-361; Immigrants: 
 alleged criminal proclivities of 
 the, 358 ; no more criminal than 
 native Americans, 359 ; Increase 
 of immigration: coincident with 
 decrease of c., 360 
 
 DANES, 79, 197, (See also: Scan- 
 dinavians) 
 
 DANGEROUS WORKING CONDI- 
 TIONS, statistics of strikes 
 against, 486 
 
 DAYS WORKED, Bituminous coal 
 mines: d. w. collated with 
 variation of number of immi- 
 grant miners and laborers in 
 Pennsylvania, 140, 141; Organ- 
 ized trades: in the State of New 
 York, and immigration, 1897- 
 1909, 144 
 
 DEMAND FOR LABOR, (See also: 
 Agriculture; Labor Market); 
 A griculture: 1 03-1 1 3 ; Charac- 
 ter and volume of immigration: 
 determined by, 102; Immigra- 
 tion and emigration: regulated 
 by, 3 ; Population of the United 
 States : not increasing as fast as, 
 84 
 
 DENMARK, 16, 179, 202, 203-205, 
 (See also: Northern and Western 
 Europe) ; Decline of emigration: 
 from, due to improvement in 
 condition of people, 205; Eco- 
 nomic conditions: of the peas- 
 ants greatly improved since the 
 '8o's, 203; Emigration: from, 
 to the United States, 1820-1910, 
 203; Immigration: to, 204; 
 Progress of manufacturing; 204 
 
 DESMOND, H. J., 73, 77 
 
 DISPLACEMENT, denned by the 
 Oxford Dictionary, 149 
 
 DISPLACEMENT, RACIAL, 415 
 
 E 
 
 EARNINGS, (See: Wages) 
 
 EASTMAN, CRYSTAL, 460, 461, 467, 
 468, 481, 482, 484 
 
 EMIGRATION, American farmers: 
 emigrating to Canada, 112; 
 Immigration : compared with, 
 90, 557, 558; Industrial crisis, 
 1907-8, net e. during, 88; 
 Monthly average: 1907-1909, 
 92; World War, net e. during, 
 498 
 
 EMPLOYMENT, Fluctuations of,i2i, 
 
 123, 137, 53i 
 
 ENGELS, FRIEDRICH, 475-476 
 
 ENGLAND, (See: United Kingdom) 
 
 ENGLISH AND WELSH, 166, 167, 
 
 168, 170, 171, 172, 262, 263, 
 
 264, 267, 268, 290, 326, 355, 
 
 356, 357, 395, 40i, 4U, 415, 
 
 425, 436, 437, 442, 447, 449, 
 
 545, 546 
 
564 
 
 Index 
 
 ENGLISH LANGUAGE, per cent 
 foreign-born able to speak the, 
 by years in the U. S., 58 
 
 F 
 FAIRCHILD, HENRY PRATT, iv; 
 
 487; 515-517; 519-529 
 FALKNER, ROLAND P., 68, 69 
 FAMILY BUDGETS, Clothing: ex- 
 penditure for, in families of un- 
 skilled laborers, by income and 
 nativity, 267; increases with 
 earnings, 266; prices paid for, 
 by recent immigrants the same 
 as by native Americans, 265; 
 race variations insignificant, 
 266; Deficit: annual, per work- 
 ing family, by occupations, 
 1885,297,551; Food: expendi- 
 tures for, by nativity and in- 
 come, 258, 260, 262; in New 
 York City, 260; Slav laborers, 
 standards of, 259; Laborers: 
 unskilled, classified by nativity 
 and source of income, New 
 Jersey, 1885, 550; Massachu- 
 setts: 1800, 1830, and 1860, 549; 
 Rent: paid by immigrants as 
 high as, or higher than, that 
 paid by native wage-earners, 
 250; by nativity, 254, 255; 
 per person, in families without 
 boarders, the same for native, 
 and foreign-born, 254, 255; 
 South Italians: food expendi- 
 tures of, compared with Ameri- 
 can families, 258; Surplus: of 
 income over expenditure, by 
 country of birth of families, 
 368; Wage-earners: classified 
 by occupations, New Jersey, 
 1885, 550 
 
 FARMHOUSE LABOR, Competition: 
 of, in the clothing industry, in 
 '40*5 and '50*5, 365; Daughters 
 of American farmers: working 
 for less than cost of living, 365 
 FARMING, (See: Agriculture) 
 FARM LABORERS, (See: Agricul- 
 tural laborers) 
 
 FATAL ACCIDENT RATE, (See also: 
 Fatal Accidents); Anthracite 
 coal mines: 1870-1909, 528; 
 decrease simultaneous with in- 
 crease of employment of Slavs 
 
 and Italians, 478; Bituminous 
 coal mines: 485; collated with 
 variation of the per cent of 
 miners of Italian and Slavic 
 parentage, 472, 555; compared 
 with railroads, 557; increase 
 due to exhaustion of mines, 480; 
 Coal mines: variation by States, 
 471; by causes and nativity, 
 474; by length of experience 
 and nativity, 477; Foreign 
 countries: compared with U. S., 
 469 
 
 FATAL ACCIDENTS, (See also: Fatal 
 Accident Rate; Work Acci- 
 dents); Coal mines: negligence 
 of the miners, 480; Railroads: 
 485; Steel mills: speeding the 
 cause of, 481 
 
 FITCH, JOHN A., 164, 395, 399~4oi, 
 405, 411-413, 520, 526, (See 
 also: Pittsburgh Survey) 
 
 FOERSTER, ROBERT F., 515-520, 
 
 525-527 
 
 FOOD, 256-265, (See also: Family 
 Budgets) ; Food: Southern iron 
 district: expenses of typical 
 households for, 549; Immigra- 
 tion Commission's data: 256, 
 257; Slavs: standards of the, 
 compared with the U. S. Navy 
 ration, 257 
 
 FOREIGN-BORN, Breadwinners: by 
 grade of occupation and na- 
 tionality, 172; immigration and 
 emigration of, 1915-1919, 559; 
 increase or decrease of, by occu- 
 pation and nationality, 1890- 
 1900, Appendix, Table XI; In- 
 crease: compared with immigra- 
 tion, 88; from Scandinavian 
 countries, compared with immi- 
 grants from Southern and East- 
 ern Europe, 1880-1910, 199 
 
 FRIDAY, DAVID, 497, 503, 504, 511 
 
 GARMENT WORKERS, 362-374, (See 
 also: Clothing Industry) ; Jews: 
 in the cities underbid by Amer- 
 ican country workers, 372; La- 
 bor organizations: affiliations of 
 Jews and Italians with, in New 
 York City above the average 
 for ' the country, 326; more 
 
Index 
 
 565 
 
 effective than among other in- 
 dustrial workers, 373 
 
 GERMAN IMMIGRANTS, 2, 3, 8, 12, 
 15, 52-54, 65, 66, 73, 76-78, 149, 
 162, 170-172, 180-196, 194, 
 228-233, 252, 253, 263, 275, 328, 
 357, 368, 369, 370, 374, 385, 395, 
 401, 414, 436, 442; Colonies: in 
 the middle of the nineteenth 
 century, 77 ; Congestion: in the 
 settlements in old New York 
 City, 65; Occupations: 1890- 
 1900, 170; Pennsylvania: in the 
 colony of, 76; Tenement houses: 
 unsanitary, in New York City 
 colonies of, in the '60 's, 232 
 
 GERMANY, (See also: German 
 Immigrants; Northern and 
 Western Europe); i, 14, 43, 52, 
 178-180, 180-196, 255, 262, 267, 
 268, 355, 356, 386, 520, 545; Ad- 
 vance: in the wages of farm 
 labor, 189, 190; Agricultural 
 progress: 189, 190; in 1895- 
 1910, 190; Coal: production of, 
 per cent increase of, 1890-1909, 
 183; Coal miners: increase of 
 annual earnings, 1890-1910, 
 1 86; Emigration: from, annual 
 average, 1875-1910, 192; to 
 countries outside of the U. S., 
 1890-1904, 195; net e. from, 
 1 80 ; of unskilled laborers to the 
 U. S., increasing with the in- 
 creased immigration to the U. 
 S., from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, 192, 193; Foreign-born: 
 by country of birth, 1880-1900, 
 545 ; engaged in gainful occupa- 
 tions, 1900, 545; population of, 
 1 80; Immigration: to, exceeds 
 emigration from, 180; to G. from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, 
 
 181, 520; Industrial expansion: 
 
 182, 520; Iron: production of, 
 1880-1910, 183; Labor: con- 
 dition of, improved, 185; de- 
 mand for, increased, 185; Mi- 
 gration: of workers from Rus- 
 sian Poland to G., 181; Rail- 
 road mileage: growth of, and 
 freight traffic, 1890-1900, 184; 
 Trade-unions: 189; member- 
 ship of, 1890-1910, 187 
 
 GREAT BRITAIN, i, 14, 17, 52, 179, 
 385, (See also: British Immi- 
 
 gration; English and Welsh; 
 Northern and Western Europe; 
 United Kingdom) ; Immigra- 
 tion: from, rise in 1897-1907, 
 213; Living conditions: im- 
 provement of, 214; Real wages: 
 1850-1900, 215 / 
 
 H 
 
 HALL, PRESCOTT F., 41, 42 
 
 HAYNES, JOHN RANDOLPH, 462, 
 464, 469, 480, 481 
 
 HEBREWS, (See: Jews) 
 
 HOFFMAN, P. L., 465, 466, 471, 
 474, 476, 477 
 
 HOLMES, JOSEPH A., 467, 468 
 
 HOME OWNERSHIP, 274-283, (See 
 also: Apartment Houses); Ages: 
 of home owners, 279-281; Bos- 
 ton: 1845-1900, 277; Cities: 
 with population of 50,000 and 
 over, percentage of native white 
 in, 278; Decreasing: with the 
 growth of urban population, 
 282; with the increase of land 
 values, 278; Irregularity of em- 
 ployment: a bar to, 274; New 
 immigrants: not long enough in 
 the U. S. to have acquired 
 homes, 282; Labor disputes: 
 handicap in, 174; Laboring 
 classes; not accessible to, 283; 
 Old immigration: 277; Real 
 estate: value of, 278-279; Ten- 
 ancy: in Boston, 1790, 1845, 
 1890, and 1900, 276; Thrift: 
 and h. o., 276 
 
 HOURS OF LABOR, 3ii~3i7, (See 
 also: Clothing Industry); Agri- 
 culture: no; American mill 
 hands: native, in the ante- 
 immigration period, 311, 312; 
 Cotton mills: h. o. 1. reduced in, 
 315; Massachusetts: 1872-1903, 
 313; New immigration: 314; 
 New York City: reduction of, 
 compared with remainder of 
 the State, 316, 317; Reduction: 
 contemporaneous with immi- 
 gration, 27; Sewing women: in 
 the middle of the nineteenth 
 century, 363; Steel industry: 
 shorter hours for foreigners 
 than for English-speaking skilled 
 and semi-skilled .employees, 314 
 
S 66 
 
 Index 
 
 HOUSING CONDITIONS, 241-256, 
 (See also: Congestion; Tene- 
 ment Houses); Cause: of bad 
 h. c. economic, not racial, 247; 
 Germans: unsanitary h. c. of, 
 in the past, 230-232; Immigra- 
 tion Commission: tendency to 
 shift the blame to the tenant, 
 249; Improvements: by Italians 
 and Jews, 66; Irish: unsanitary 
 h. c. of, in the past, 230-232; 
 Italian district: improved h. c. 
 in the, 66, 234; Jewish districts: 
 improved h. c. in the, 66, 234; 
 Landlords: responsibility of, 
 247; Native white: New Eng- 
 land working girls in the '40*8, 
 241; sewing women, squalid 
 h. c. in the past, 231; unskilled 
 laborers in Southern mill towns, 
 246; Old immigration: cellar 
 population in New York City, 
 230; Massachusetts towns, h. c. 
 in, 243 ; rear tenements in New 
 York City, 233; shanty dwell- 
 ers in Massachusetts in the 
 '70*5, 244; unsanitary tene- 
 ments in Boston, 241, 242 
 
 HOWARD, EARL DEAN, 185, 186, 
 189, 190 
 
 HUNGARIANS, (See: Magyars, 
 Slavs) 
 
 HUNGARY, 98, 100 
 
 HUNTER, ROBERT, 40, 45 
 
 ILLINOIS, 11, 134, 135, 300, 301, 
 319, 334. 428-431, 433, 447, 44, 
 453, 471, 472, 473, 484, 534, 
 
 T 535, 538, 539, 540, 554, 557 
 
 ILLITERACY, immigration from 
 Bulgaria, Greece, Russia, and 
 Servia compared with popula- 
 tion of same countries, 71 ; 
 Italian: statistics of, 80; Sta- 
 tistics: 70, 80 
 
 IMMIGRANT COLONIES, Irish and 
 German in middle of nineteenth 
 century, 77 
 
 IMMIGRANTS, Connections: in the 
 U. S., 94; Farmers: number of, 
 negligible at all periods, 67; 
 Imported: myth of, 3, 99; 
 Occupations: per cent distribu- 
 tion by, 1861-1910, 67; Old: 
 
 majority unskilled, 67; Skilled: 
 proportion of, same for last half- 
 century, 67 
 
 IMMIGRATION, Annual average: by 
 occupations, 1 86 1-1910, 503 ; 
 Assisted: 96; Breadwinners, 
 immigration and emigration of, 
 559, net i. of, 1915-1919, 498; 
 Business conditions: and, 1880- 
 1910, 87; Compared: with emi- 
 gration, 88, 546 ; Decline of, 
 493, 498; Monthly average: 
 compared with immigration, 
 1907-1909, 92; Objections: to, 
 40; Old: compared with New, 
 6 1 -8 1 ; distribution, before 
 1840, 63; indentured servants, 
 immigrants a century ago 
 mostly, 62; Opposition: to, by 
 organized labor antedates new, 
 78; to quantity not quality, 79; 
 Quality of: European opinion, 
 .72; Immigration Commission, 
 conclusion of, 72; intellectu- 
 ally average immigrant above 
 average of countrymen at home, 
 70; standard not lowered, 69; 
 Restriction of, probable effects 
 of, 487-492; 511; Tractability: 
 of old and new, 346; Volume: 
 how regulated, 93 
 
 IMMIGRATION COMMISSION, Con- 
 clusions: of the, 49, 72 ; contra- 
 ' dieted by its statistics, 325 
 
 INDUCED IMMIGRATION, uncon- 
 firmed tales of, 391 
 
 INDUSTRIAL ACTIVITY, Immigra- 
 tion: and, 86; Population: and, 
 for the past twenty years, 82 
 
 INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Commis- 
 sion on, 493, 494, 500 
 
 IRELAND, 2, 14, 17, 43, 65, 178, 
 179, 210, 215-221, 244, 245, 
 55.0, 551, (See also: Congestion; 
 Irish; Northern and _ Western 
 Europe; United Kingdom); 
 Emigration: from, 1851-1908, 
 216; decreasing since 1 860, 2 1 6 ; 
 by destination, 1876-1908, 217; 
 Farm laborers: rise in wages of, 
 219; Housing: in rural areas, 
 186^-1901, 219; Land reform: 
 effects of, 217, 218; Recent 
 progress: 217-219 
 
 IRISH, 12-14, 17, 25, 52, 54, 57, 
 64-67, 69, 73, 77, 149, !6i, 166, 
 
Index 
 
 567 
 
 169-172, 178, 179, 2IO, 212, 
 229-232, 244, 247, 252, 253, 255, 
 260-263, 267, 275, 290, 295, 328, 
 
 355, 356, 357, 364, 365, 374, 385, 
 386, 394, 395, 401, 414, 415, 425, 
 436, 437, 442, 447, 449, 545, 546, 
 (See also: Ireland) ; Congestion: 
 in the settlements of New York 
 City in the past, 65; Farm 
 work: reluctance of the early 
 immigrants toward, 66; Immi- 
 grant colonies: in the middle of 
 the nineteenth century, 77; Oc- 
 cupations: in the U. S., 1890- 
 1900, 169; Pauperism: in Bos- 
 ton, 1837-1845, 356; Standard 
 of living: of early immigrants, 
 64; Sweatshops: in the 'so's, 
 364; Tenement houses: unsani- 
 tary, in the I. colonies of New 
 York City in the '6o's, 232 
 IRON AND STEEL INDUSTRY, (See 
 also: Iron and Steel Workers); 
 Expansion: of, 158-160; Tech- 
 nical revolution: in the, 399 
 
 IRON AND STEEL WORKERS, 394- 
 
 413, (See also: Aristocracy of 
 Labor; Rolling Mills; Un- 
 skilled Laborers); Amalga- 
 mated Association: of, common 
 laborers barred, 411; decline 
 due to substitution of ma- 
 chinery for skill, 412; Birds of 
 passage: by race, 75; Crowding 
 out: of English-speaking work- 
 men by immigrants, none, 395; 
 Earnings: in the Pittsburgh and 
 Southern districts. 408; Eight- 
 hour day: demand of the em- 
 ployers, in th '8o's resisted, by 
 the Amalgamated Association, 
 410, 411; Highly paid men: a 
 small fraction of the force in the 
 past, 395; Hours of labor: 
 shorter for unskilled foreign- 
 ers than for English-speaking 
 skilled and semi-skilled, 314; 
 Machinery: skill displaced by, 
 399; Months of employment: 
 native and foreign-born male, 
 by per cent distribution, 127; 
 Race: 1880, 1890, and 1900, 
 159; 1890-1900, in the prin- 
 cipal cities of the Middle West, 
 1 60; and skill, 402; Racial 
 stratification: 402, 403; Skilled: 
 
 earnings in Eastern and South- 
 ern mills, 407; proportion of, 
 162; Sunday work: general 
 rule before period of New Im- 
 migration, 409; Twelve-hour 
 day: insisted on by piece work- 
 ers in the '8o's, 410, 411; Un- 
 skilled: proportion of, 162; 
 Wages: 403; in 1884, 396; in 
 1880-1908, 398, 553; by occu- 
 pations, 1880-1908, 397; of 
 skilled men higher in Pittsburgh 
 with, than in the South with- 
 out, immigrant competition, 
 405 ; of skilled men in the Pitts- 
 burgh mills reduced since 1892, 
 403, 404; vary inversely with 
 the ratio of recent immigrants, 
 408 
 
 IRREGULARITY OF EMPLOYMENT, 
 migratory worker the product 
 of, 435 
 
 ITALIANS, 3, 7, 15, 16, 20, 22, 32, 
 37, 43, 47, 65, 72, 79, 80, 85, 
 91, 99, 120, 162, 170-172, 193, 
 200, 201, 209, 234, 237, 238, 240, 
 253, 255, 258-263, 267-269, 290, 
 326, 328, 345, 349, 351, 355, 
 356-359, 368-371, 374, 385, 386, 
 388, 391, 394, 428, 437, 442, 443, 
 449, 450, 453, 458, 484, 545, 
 546, (See also: South Italians) ; 
 Housing conditions: improved 
 by, 66; improved in the I. 
 district, 234; Illiteracy: statis- 
 tics, 80; Labor organizations: 
 affiliation of clothing workers 
 with, above the average for the 
 country, 326 
 
 ITALY, 32, 69, 72, 93, 181, 349, 350, 
 358, 359, (See also: Italians); 
 Labor organizations: 349; agri- 
 cultural, 350; Strikes: of agri- 
 cultural laborers, 350 
 
 JENKS AND LAUCK, 43, 44, 65, 68, 
 84, 85, 126, 163, 164, 173, 245, 
 247, 248, 250, 251, 271, 272, 273, 
 275, 280, 285, 287, 288, 290, 302, 
 303, 346, 35i, 36o, 371, 458, 460 
 
 JENKS, JEREMIAH W., (See: Jenks 
 and Lauck) 
 
 JEWS, 3, 20, 25, 32, 65, 66, 71, 72, 
 228, 234, 238, 240, 253, 280, 
 
568 
 
 Index 
 
 326, 328, 351, 356, 362, 363, 368, 
 
 369, 370, 371, 372, 374, (See 
 also: Russians); Housing con- 
 ditions: improved, in the J. 
 districts, 66, 234; Labor organi- 
 zations: affiliation of J. clothing 
 workers with, in New York 
 City above the average for the 
 country, 326; Underbidding: of 
 J. by American country work- 
 ers, 372 
 
 LABOR, condition of, has not de- 
 teriorated in the U. S., 23 
 
 LABOR AGENTS, before the immi- 
 gration era, 119 
 
 LABOR ARISTOCRACY, (See: Aris- 
 tocracy of Labor) 
 
 LABOR COMPETITION, Immigrants: 
 do not undercut union wages, 
 378; Southern white: keeping 
 down the wages of immigrants 
 in the North, 381 
 
 LABOR MARKET, immigration and 
 the, 82-102, 498-500; mobility 
 of labor, 499-5 
 
 LABOR ORGANIZATIONS, 325-352, 
 (See also: Coal Mines; Cotton 
 Mills; Garment Workers; Iron 
 and Steel W9rkers; Woolen 
 Mills); Bituminous coal mines: 
 445 ; Coal miners: non-English- 
 speaking, affiliated with, 352, 
 353 ; union of, recognized by the 
 Steel Trust, 453 ; Date of organi- 
 zation: in principal industrial 
 States, 334; Ephemeral: previous 
 to 1880, 330; Garment workers: 
 Jewish and Italian, union affilia- 
 tions above the average for the 
 country, 326; Growth: since 
 1890,333; Immigrants: discrim- 
 ination against, 347; Immigra- 
 tion: effects of, on 1. o., 376, 377; 
 Machinery: effect upon craft 
 unions, 351; Membership: na- 
 tivity, 552; and immigration, 
 New York State, 552; in the 
 State of New York, and im- 
 migration to the State of 
 New York, 1897-1910, 336; 
 foreign-born predominating in 
 the '8o's, 330, 331; proportion 
 of industrial wage-earners or- 
 
 ganized, 340, 553; race not a 
 factor, 327; rising and falling 
 with rise and fall of immigra- 
 tion, 30; Native Americans: 
 aloofness from, 339; New York 
 City: stronger than in the re- 
 mainder of the State, 341, 343; 
 New York State, stronger than 
 in Kansas, 337, 339; Progress: 
 greater progress coincident with 
 the great tide of immigration, 
 3331 Proportion: organized, na- 
 tives and immigrants, 327, 328; 
 Recent immigrants: home train- 
 ing in organization, 32, 349; 
 organizing along industrial lines, 
 413; as strongly organized as 
 natives and older immigrants, 
 327; Skilled: interests of, con- 
 flict with those of the unskilled, 
 348; Unskilled: not eligible to 
 membership in craft unions, 
 346; organization among the, 
 
 32, 349 
 
 LABOR PROBLEM, immigration not 
 the cause of, 34 
 
 LABOR UNIONS, (See: Labor Or- 
 ganizations) 
 
 LABORERS, (See: Unskilled Lab- 
 orers) 
 
 LAUCK, W. JETT, 49, 265, 384, 388, 
 494, 495, 496, 501, 511, (See 
 also: Jenks and Lauck) 
 
 LAWRENCE, MASSACHUSETTS, 33, 
 348, 384-393, (See also: Strikes; 
 Wages; Woolen and Worsted 
 Mills; Worsted Mills); strike of 
 1912, 348; and public opinion, 
 
 384 
 LEISERSON, WILLIAM M., 290, 
 
 44, 454 
 LITHUANIANS, 32, 55, 56, 57, 75, 
 
 228, 253, 328, 351, 368, 370, 
 T 442, 456 
 
 LITMAN, SIMON, 502, 503 
 LIVING EXPENSES, (See: Family 
 
 Budgets) 
 LODGERS, (See: Boarders and 
 
 Lodgers) 
 
 M 
 
 MACHINE MINING, (See also: Min- 
 ing Machine) ; Bituminous coal: 
 per cent of, machine mined, and 
 per cent ratio of miners from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe, 
 
Index 569 
 
 by States, 553; Economies: of, 
 426, 427 
 
 MACHINERY, (See also: Agricul- 
 ture; Agricultural Laborers; 
 Iron and Steel Workers); Ef- 
 fects: in general, 231, 525, 526; 
 upon craft unions, 351; Immi- 
 gration: New, and, 289; sub- 
 stitute for, 492 ; Rate of wages: 
 introduction determined by, 290 
 
 MAGYARS, 162, 257, 442, 443, 449, 
 450, 458 (See also: Hungary) 
 
 MANUFACTURES, wage - earners, 
 1879-1909, 151 
 
 MARX, KARL, 124, 125, 291 
 
 MASSACHUSETTS, 27, 138, 139, 
 174-176, 224, 225, 243, 244, 295, 
 300, 301, 311, 313, 314, 319, 321, 
 333, 334, 343, 344, 375, 378-380, 
 382, 383, 392, 523, 524, 534, 535, 
 540, 541, 551; Hours of labor: 
 1872-1903, 313; Immigrant 
 breadwinners: destined for, 
 1897-1908, 139; Racial stratifi- 
 cation: 1900-1905, 173; Strikes: 
 1830-1905, 344; Textile mills: 
 percentage of immigrants from 
 Southern and Eastern Europe 
 employed in, 1880-1900, 370; 
 Unemployment: of factory work- 
 ers, and immigration, 139; 
 Wages and cost of living: 1800, 
 1830, and i860, 295, 296, 521; 
 in the '7o's, 295; Woolen mills: 
 comparative statistics of strikes 
 in, 392 
 
 MAYO-SMITH, RICHMOND, 46, 69, 
 89, 292 
 
 MIGRATORY WORKERS, created by 
 irregularity of employment, 435 
 
 MINERS, (See also: Fatal Acci- 
 dents: Labor Organizations; 
 Unemployment); Native white: 
 decrease of the number of, by 
 States, 1890-1900, 158; Racial 
 displacement: of natives by 
 immigrants, none, 156, 157 
 
 MINING MACHINE, Pick miner: 
 displaced by the, 425 ; Substitute 
 for immigration: 425; Unskilled 
 immigrants: employment of, the 
 effect not the cause of the intro- 
 duction of the m. m., 425 
 
 MITCHELL, JOHN, 41, 46 
 
 MITCHELL, WESLEY C., 308, 507 
 
 MONEY SENT ABROAD, by immi- 
 
 grants, 269; mercantilist objec- 
 tion to, 271 
 
 N 
 
 NATIONALITIES, principal, of male 
 breadwinners classified by occu- 
 pation groups, 1900, 171 
 
 NATIVE-BORN, decrease of, by 
 occupations, 1890-1900, 152 
 
 NATIVE BREADWINNERS, decrease 
 ofi by occupations in Mass., 
 1900-1905, 175 
 
 NATIVE WHITE, of native parent- 
 age, males, decrease in selected 
 occupations, compared with loss 
 by death, 1890-1900, 153 
 
 NEARING, SCOTT, 293, 302, 519 
 
 NEGROES, migration of, during the 
 World War, 507, 508 
 
 NEW IMMIGRATION, compared with 
 the Old, 61-81 
 
 NEW YORK CITY, 7, 20, 25, 28, 32, 
 63, 66, 67, 119, 120, 121, 149, 
 229-241, 260, 316, 317, 326, 335, 
 
 337, 340-343, 354-357, 3^3, 365, 
 367, 369, (See also: Family 
 Budgets; Congestion); Cellar 
 population: of the '40*3, 230; 
 Congestion: in the Irish and 
 German settlements of the 
 past, 65 ; Hours of labor: reduc- 
 tion of, compared with the 
 remainder of the State, 316,317; 
 Labor organizations: affiliation 
 of Jewish and Italian clothing 
 workers with, above the average 
 for the country, 326; member- 
 ship of, compared with New 
 York State, 341, 343; Pauper- 
 ism: lodgers at the municipal 
 lodging nouses, by nativity, 
 1908, 355; Paupers: nativity, 
 1854-1860, and 1885-1895, 356; 
 by nativity and cause, 356, 357 
 NEW YORK STATE, 27, 31, 140, 
 143, 144, 146, 300, 301, 315-317, 
 319, 32i, 335-343, 36o, 383, 534, 
 535, 540, 554, 555; Hours of 
 labor: compared with New York 
 City, 317; Membership of labor 
 organizations: compared with 
 Kansas, 339; compared with 
 New York City, 342, 343; per- 
 centage of wage-earners organ- 
 ized, 1900-1909, 553; rising and 
 
570 
 
 Index 
 
 falling with immigration, 335, 
 
 55 2 
 
 NEWSHOLME, ARTHUR, 226, 528 
 
 NORTHERN AND WESTERN EU- 
 ROPE, Emigration: from, 177- 
 220; causes of decrease, 13; 
 cannot keep pace with demand 
 for labor in the U. S., 177; Im- 
 migration: to the United States 
 could not replace immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, 220 
 
 NORWAY, 179, 202-203, (See also: 
 Northern and Western Europe) ; 
 Immigration: from, to the U. S., 
 202; greatest in 1901-1910, 202; 
 Recent industrial development: 
 202 
 
 NORWEGIANS, 52, 197, 252, 253, 
 264, (See also: Norway; Scan- 
 dinavians) 
 
 OCCUPATIONS OF IMMIGRANTS, 
 (See: Immigrants) 
 
 OLD IMMIGRATION, (See: Immigra- 
 tion) 
 
 OPPOSITION TO IMMIGRATION, (See: 
 Immigration) 
 
 PAUPERISM, 353~358; Decrease: 
 during period of greatest im- 
 migration, 353; Industrial in- 
 validism: p. due to, 357; New 
 immigration: p. less frequent 
 among the, than among the 
 Old, 354; New York City: 
 lodgers at municipal lodging 
 houses, by nativity, 1908, 355; 
 Racial displacement: p. not 
 due to, 355, 356; Unemploy- 
 ment: a minor cause of p., 357 
 
 PAUPERS, English and Irish: 1837- 
 1845, 356; New York City: 
 nativity of p., in the past, 356, 
 357 
 
 PEARSON, KARL, 226, 528 
 
 PENNSYLVANIA, 6, 9, 11, 33, 100, 
 119, 134, 135, 140, 141, 151, 249, 
 300, 301, 319, 321, 343, 344, 371, 
 372, 383, 414, 415, 419-422, 
 428-431, 437, 439, 442, 445, 446, 
 449, 454-456, 461, 462, 466, 
 471-473, 48o, 481, 534, 535, 538- 
 
 549, 555-557; (See also: Coal 
 Mines, Bituminous; Coal 
 Mines, Anthracite) ; Bitumi- 
 nous coal mines: days worked, 
 and number of immigrant min- 
 ers and laborers, 141 ; Strikes: 
 
 1835-1905, 344 
 PHILADELPHIA, 25, 363, 372 
 PITTSBURGH, 24, 306, 394, 401- 
 
 410, 439, 454, 460, 484 
 PITTSBURGH SURVEY, 164, 306, 
 395, 399-402, 406, 411-413, 454, 
 460 
 
 PLUNKETT, HORACE, 218 
 POLAND, 56, 100, 181, 182, 190 
 POLES, 14, 16, 32, 54, 55, 57, 59, 
 60, 75, 99, 162, 170, 171, 172, 
 181, 182, 190, 228, 238, 251, 253, 
 269, 328, 368, 369, 370, 378, 380, 
 385, 386, 442, 456, 471; Eng- 
 lish-speaking, by years in the 
 U. S., 78 
 PRATT, EDWARD EWING, 235-239, 
 
 276, 341 
 PREJUDICE, against immigrants in 
 
 the past, 73 
 PRICES, control of, 306, 510, 511 
 
 
 
 8UAINTANCE, H. W., IO3, IO9, IIO 
 UALITY OF IMMIGRATION, (See 
 
 Immigration) 
 
 RACE CLASSIFICATION, fallacy of 
 the, adopted by the Immigra- 
 tion Commission, 250 
 
 RACE DISTINCTION, dominant'idea 
 of the investigation of the Im- 
 migration Commission, 55 
 
 RACE PREJUDICE, motive of oppo- 
 sition to recent immigrants, 457 
 
 RACE SUICIDE, 221-227; Birth 
 rate: Commission of Inquiry 
 into the Declining, report of, 
 226-227; decline of, among the 
 better- to-do, 226; among the 
 English aristocracy, 528; de- 
 cline of, begins in 1810-1830, 
 2237 native, decreasing with 
 rural population, 224; rise in 
 social condition cause of decline 
 of, 226; varies inversely with 
 income, 226; Walker's theory 
 
Index 
 
 of the decline in the native, 221, 
 528; Immigration: unrelated 
 to, 18; Universal: among social 
 classes not affected by immi- 
 grant competition, 226; Wat- 
 son's forecast: of the population 
 of the U. S., 222, 223; World- 
 wide: 224 
 
 RACIAL DISPLACEMENT, (See also: 
 Racial Stratification); Laborers: 
 none, of native, by immi- 
 grants, 156, 157; Miners: none, 
 of native, by immigrants, 156, 
 157; Native Americans: em- 
 ployed in increased numbers 
 with increasing immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, 158, 1 60; Negligible: 
 151, 152, 176 
 
 RACIAL STRATIFICATION, 148-176, 
 150, 151; Massachusetts: 1900- 
 f905 J 73J Occupations: read- 
 justment on the scale of, 170; 
 Shifting: of English and Welsh, 
 Irish and Germans, from lower 
 paid to more remunerative 
 occupations, 165 
 
 RAILROAD EMPLOYEES, wages of, 
 1891-1909, 304 
 
 REAL WAGES, (See: Wages) 
 
 RENT, of native American wage- 
 earners in small towns lower 
 than that of immigrant workers 
 in large cities, 255; increase of, 
 502, (See also: Family Budgets) 
 
 RIPLEY, WILLIAM Z., 224 
 
 ROBERTS, PETER, 259, 444, 445, 
 455, 456, 481 
 
 ROLLING MILLS, (See also: Iron 
 and Steel Industry, Iron and 
 Steel Workers), Laborers: wages 
 of, 1884-1902, 398; Rates of 
 wages: classification of em- 
 ployees by, 1884, 396 
 
 Ross, EDWARD A., 140 
 
 RURAL DEPOPULATION, 103-104; 
 migration of native American 
 stock to city, 104; relative and 
 absolute, 103 
 
 RURAL TERRITORY, decrease of the 
 population of, 1900-1910, 104 
 
 RUSSIA, 32, 69, 71, 146, 1 81, 349- 
 351; strikes in, 349; unem- 
 ployment insurance, 146 
 
 RUSSIANS, 32, 71, 75, 190, 228, 
 238, 255, 260, 262, 263, 264, 267, 
 
 268, 351, 354, 355, 357, 369, 370, 
 385, 386, 388, (See also: Jews) 
 
 SABATH, A. J., 347 
 SAVINGS, Of immigrants: disposi- 
 tion of, does not affect American 
 wage-earners, 271; investments 
 in their home countries, 270; 
 Of wage-earners: small margin 
 of .income left for, 267 
 SCANDINAVIANS, i, 16, 178, 196- 
 201, 355, 386, 548; (See also: 
 Danes, Norwegians, Swedes) ; 
 Competing with new immigrants: 
 200, 20 1 ; Immigration to the 
 United States: of breadwinners 
 highest in 1901-1910, 196; 
 1881-1910, 196; course of, 
 turned eastward, 197, 198; In- 
 crease: of, in the U. S., by 
 geographic division, 1880-1910, 
 198, 199; In the United States: 
 compared with Southern and 
 Eastern Europeans by States, 
 1880, 1890, 1900, and 1910, 
 545; Occupations: 1881-1910, 
 20 1 ; Recent immigrants: mostly 
 not of the family type, 197 
 Scisco, Louis Dow, 73, 77 
 SCOTCH, 12, 52, 75, 161, 171, 172, 
 252, 253, 264, 355, 356, 414, 415, 
 442, 447, 545, 546; immigra- 
 tion not decreased, 173 
 SCOTLAND, (See: United Kingdom) 
 SIMONS, A. M., 62, 63, 115 
 SLAVS, Food: standards of, com- 
 pared with United States navy 
 rations, 257; Organization: ca- 
 pacity for, 455, 456; Wages: of 
 unskilled laborers increased, 
 
 453, 454 
 
 SOUTH ITALIANS, 75, 247, 249, 
 251, (See also: Italians); Food 
 expenditures: compared with 
 Americans generally, 258; with 
 native white workers in the 
 South, 258 
 
 STANDARD OF LIVING, 228-273, 
 (See also: Boarders and Lodgers; 
 Congestion; Family Budgets); 
 Children's earnings: source of 
 higher s. o. 1., maintained by 
 Americans and Americanized 
 families, 22, 285; Old immigra- 
 
572 
 
 Index 
 
 tion: standard low, 64; Race 
 standard: existence of, not 
 proved, 264; Recent immigrants: 
 standard of, not inferior to that 
 of their predecessors, 19 
 
 STEAMSHIP AGENTS, effect of so- 
 licitation by, negligible, 97 
 
 STEEL MILLS, (See: Iron and Steel 
 Workers; Rolling Mills) 
 
 STEEL WORKERS, fatal accidents, 
 speeding the cause of, 481, (See 
 also: Iron and Steel Workers; 
 Rolling Mills) 
 
 STEERAGE RATES, effect of recent 
 increase upon quality of im- 
 migration, 69 
 
 STRATIFICATION, OCCUPATIONAL, 
 caste prejudice against the 
 immigrant, the outgrowth of, 
 424 
 
 STREIGHTOFF, F. N., 246, 248, 255, 
 276, 294 
 
 STRIKE BREAKERS, native Ameri- 
 cans as, 345; recent immi- 
 grants as, 346 
 
 STRIKES, (See also: Clothing In- 
 dustry; Cotton Mills; Strike 
 Breakers; Woolen Mills); An- 
 thracite coal mines: 1902, 456; 
 Coal mines: Southern and East- 
 ern Europeans identified with 
 every strike in, 447, 448; 
 Immigrants: have stood by the 
 unions, 378; Immigration: and, 
 1886-1905, 345 ; increasing with, 
 344; Lawrence, Massachusetts: 
 392; Massachusetts: 1830-1905, 
 344; More numerous: since 1881, 
 343, 344; Pennsylvania: 1835- 
 I9<>5 344; Russia: 349; Woolen 
 and worsted mills: comparative 
 statistics of s. in, 392; World 
 War, s. during, 505 
 
 SUMNER, HELEN L., 115, 120, 230, 
 241, 363, 364, 365, (See also: 
 Women in Industry) 
 
 SUNDAY WORK, (See: Iron and 
 Steel Workers) 
 
 SUNDBARG, GUSTAV, 2OI, 2O6, 2O7 
 
 SUTHERLAND, HUGH, 217, 218, 220 
 
 SWEATSHOPS, Irish, in the 'sp's, 
 364; older than immigration, 
 362 
 
 SWEDEN, 16, 179, 205-209, (See 
 also: Northern and Western 
 Europe) ; Emigration: from cities 
 
 and rural districts, 1881-1907, 
 206; by destination, 1861-1908, 
 205; Immigration: to, 206; 1881- 
 1908, 207; Recent industrial 
 development: 207; Rural emi- 
 gration: decline of, due to small 
 demand for farm help in the 
 U. S., 205, 206 
 
 SWEDES, 52, 75, 79, 161, 170-172, 
 197, 255, 262, 267, 268, 328, 
 (See also: Scandinavians; North- 
 ern and Western Europe) 
 
 TENEMENT HOUSES, (See also: 
 Congestion; Home Ownership; 
 Housing Conditions); One-fam- 
 ily residence: made over into, 
 229; Past and present: in Bos- 
 ton, 241 ; Unsanitary conditions: 
 in the old Irish and German col- 
 onies of New York City, 232 
 
 TEXTILE MILLS, percentage of 
 immigrants from Southern and 
 Eastern Europe employed, 
 1880-1900, 379 
 
 TRACTABILITY, of old and new 
 immigrants, 346 
 
 TRADE-UNIONS, (See also: Labor 
 Organizations) ; mostly confined 
 to skilled occupations, 346, 377 
 
 TRZCINSKI, J., 181, 191 
 
 TWELVE-HOUR DAY, (See: Iron and 
 Steel Workers) 
 
 UNDESIRABLE IMMIGRATION, defi- 
 nitions of, 41 
 
 UNEMPLOYMENT, 114-147; Aus- 
 tralia: 145; Bituminous coal 
 miners: 132; collated with vari- 
 ation of the percentage of for- 
 eign-born miners, 134; Causes: 
 4, 114-125; Coal mines: part 
 time employment in lieu of u., 
 434; Cotton mills: 132; Cyclical 
 variations: 1888-1908, in Mas- 
 sachusetts, 138; Factory workers: 
 u^_ among, and immigration, 
 Massachusetts, 139; Foreign- 
 born: variation of the percentage 
 of, collated with u., by areas, 
 130,131; by geographical divi- 
 sions, 128; in inverse ratio to u., 
 
Index 
 
 573 
 
 129; Immigration: and u., 125- 
 147, 432, 433, 434; not a con- 
 tributory cause of, 145; varies 
 inversely with, 5; Labor reserve: 
 123, 125; Manufactures: aver- 
 age number of male wage- 
 earners employed, by months, 
 118; variations by States, 129; 
 Measure: of, 121, 125; Monthly 
 variations: in the State of New 
 York, 1902-1909, 125; 1916- 
 1918, 558: Native: and foreign- 
 born workmen equally affected 
 by, 126; Occupational varia- 
 tions: 131; collated with per 
 cent of foreign-born, 133, 508; 
 Restriction of immigration: no 
 relief for u., 35, 488, 489; 
 Remedy: 146; Seasonal varia- 
 tions: 115; Unskilled laborers: 
 132; Working days: number of, 
 in New York, 1897-1908, 142, 
 143 ; in Pennsylvania coal mines, 
 1901-1909, 140 
 
 UNITED KINGDOM, 178, 209-215, 
 520-522, (See also: Ireland; 
 Northern and Western Europe) ; 
 Emigration by destination: gross, 
 1840-1909, 212, 546; net, 1895- 
 1909, 213, 214; Immigration: 
 to the U. S., from, 1890-1909, 
 not below normal, 213 
 
 UNITED MINE WORKERS, (See also: 
 Coal Miners; Labor Organiza- 
 tions); growth of, 447; wage 
 conferences with mine operators 
 in the bituminous coal fields, 
 
 T 439, 450 
 
 UNSKILLED LABORERS, (See also: 
 Agriculture; Family Budgets; 
 Hours of Labor; Housing Con- 
 ditions; Illiteracy; Iron and 
 Steel Workers; Labor Organiza- 
 tions; Occupations of Immi- 
 grants; Racial Displacement; 
 Rolling Mills; Slavs; Unem- 
 ployment; Woolen and Worsted 
 Mills); Craft unions: barred 
 from, 346; interests conflicting 
 with, 348; Displacement: of 
 native, by immigrants, none, 
 J 5 6 J 57; Increase: of the 
 number of, by race and nativity, 
 1890-1900, 156; Iron and steel 
 mills: wages rising, 397; Pre- 
 dominant among the immigrants: 
 
 68; economic reason for, 19; 
 Rolling mills: wages in 1884- 
 1902, 398 ; Slav: food standards, 
 259; Unemployed: and per cent 
 foreign-born, 136, 538; Wages: 
 in agriculture and other pur- 
 suits, in; in the past, 295 
 UNSKILLED WORKERS, (See: Un- 
 skilled Laborers) 
 
 W 
 
 WAGE-EARNERS, in manufactures, 
 1879-1909, 151 
 
 WAGES, 284-310, (See also: Coal 
 Miners; Coal Mines; Conges- 
 tion; Cotton Mills; Iron and 
 Steel Workers; Wages and the 
 Cost of Living; Woolen and 
 Worsted Mills) ', Advancing: more 
 slowly than the cost of living, 
 26; with the employment of 
 large numbers of immigrants, 
 24; Agricultural laborers: com- 
 pared with other unskilled, no, 
 in; Building trades, 521; Cler- 
 ical help: w. of, low, 304; Coal 
 mines: 305; Cotton mills: 1875- 
 1908, 375, 376; upward move- 
 ment of w. since period of New 
 Immigration, 375; Country com- 
 petition: daughters of American 
 farmers working for less than 
 the cost of living, 365; native 
 Americans undercut wages of 
 immigrants, 298; Difference: in, 
 due to grade of service not to 
 country of birth, 284; not de- 
 termined by distinction of race, 
 288, 289; Earnings: annual, of 
 male and female employees in 
 manufactures, and proportion 
 of foreign-born, in principal 
 States, 300, 301; variation by 
 States, 299; Immigrants: do not 
 undercut w., 23, 378; female, 
 earnings of, higher than those of 
 native Americans, 370; re- 
 cently landed, not engaged at 
 less than the prevailing rates, 
 285; Increase: actual, result of 
 industrial expansion, 302; hy- 
 pothetical, without immigration 
 from Southern and Eastern 
 Europe, 306; Laborers: in the 
 '40*5, 295 ; in rolling mills, 1 884- 
 
574 
 
 Index 
 
 1902, 398; Large and small 
 cities: comparative w. in, 299; 
 Older employees: w. of, kept up 
 by immigration from Southern 
 and Eastern Europe, 309; Past: 
 real w. of sewing-women lower 
 than to-day, 364, 365; Purchas- 
 ing power, of, during the war, 
 500-504; Railroad employees: 
 303; Relation of rent: to, 250; 
 Scarcity of labor: effect of, 489, 
 521; Southern white competition: 
 tends to keep down the w. of 
 immigrants in the North, 383; 
 Statistics: defects of w., 293; 
 Steel mills: 305; in 1880-1908, 
 553; Urban and rural manufac- 
 tures: 298; Worsted mills: at 
 Lawrence, w. of skilled and 
 unskilled operatives in, 1889- 
 
 1909, 389 
 
 WAGES AND THE COST OF LIVING, 
 in Massachusetts, 1800, 1830 
 and 1860, 295, 296; during the 
 Civil War, 307, 308; in the 
 'jo's, 295; in the '8o's, 297; 
 during the World War, 500- 
 
 504 
 
 WALES, (See: United Kingdom) 
 
 WALKER, FRANCIS A., 18, 61, 64, 
 65, 221-223, 251 
 
 WARNE, FRANK JULIAN, 447, 453 
 
 WATSON, ELKANAH, 222, 223 
 
 WELSH, 12, 13, 52, 75, 161, 252, 
 (See also: English and Welsh) 
 
 WEYL, WALTER E., 46 
 
 WILLCOX, WALTER F., 223, 224 
 
 WILLIAMS, WILLIAM, 69 
 
 WILLIS, H. PARKER, 51 
 
 WOMEN IN INDUSTRY, 107, 115, 
 120, 230, 241, 312, 313, 345, 363, 
 508, (See also: Sweatshops; 
 Wages) 
 
 WOOLEN AND WORSTED MILLS, 
 384-393; Americans of native 
 stock: coming back to, since 
 arrival of new immigrants, 387; 
 not forced out by recent im- 
 migrants, 385; number of, 
 employed at Lawrence, 1900- 
 
 387; Recent immigrants: 
 strike record of, 392; Strikes: 
 comparative statistics of, 392; 
 Wages: at Lawrence, 1889-1909, 
 389; stationary prior to the 
 New Immigration, increasing 
 since, 388 ; of unskilled laborers 
 increased at higher rate than 
 those of skilled operatives, 388, 
 
 389 
 
 WORK ACCIDENTS, 458-486, (See 
 also: Fatal Accident Rate; 
 Fatal Accidents); Coal mines: 
 Americans, compared with Irish, 
 57; carelessness of mine man- 
 agers, 465; cause of, competi- 
 tion among coal operators, 29, 
 467, 468; increasing with prog- 
 ress in engineering, 466; Irish, 
 compared with Americans, 57; 
 Lithuanians, compared with 
 Poles, 55; opinions of experts 
 on the causes of, 462; Poles, 
 compared with Lithuanians, 55; 
 preventable by legislation and 
 efficient inspection, 468, 469; 
 prevention of, expensive, 464; 
 Railroads: compared with coal 
 mines, 484; Responsibility: for, 
 shifted to recent immigrants, 
 458, 459 
 
 WORKING DAYS, average number, 
 per man increased with recent 
 immigration, 436, 437 
 
 WORLD WAR, lessons of, 493-511; 
 Child labor: increase of, 508, 509; 
 Collective bargaining: 505; Con- 
 trpct laborers: 498-499, 530; 
 Emigration: net, 498; Immigra- 
 tion and emigration: 558 ; Strikes: 
 505; Wages and the cost of liv- 
 ing: 500-504; Women in indus- 
 try: 508 
 
 WORSTED MILLS, (See: Woolen 
 and Worsted Mills) 
 
 ZAHN, FRIEDRICH, 180, 183, 185, 
 186, 189-191 
 
 THE END 
 
14 DAY USE 
 
 RETURN TO DESK FROM WHICH BORROWED 
 
 LOAN DEPT. 
 
 RENEWALS ONLY TEL. NO. 642-3405 
 
 This book is due on the last date stamped below, or 
 
 on the date to which renewed. 
 Renewed books are subject to immediate recall. 
 
 ^2 6 '69 -a AM 
 LOAM DEPT. 
 
 RBTURNEr ro 
 
 APR I 8 19?n 
 
 MWNMlBW 
 
 LD 21A-38m-5,'68 
 (J401slO)476B 
 
 AUTO.DISC.APR27 '87 
 
 MAY 
 
 DEC.OH987 
 
 General Library 
 
 University of California 
 
 Berkeley 
 
A, 93351 
 
 U.C. BERKELEY LIBRARIES 
 
 6003017855 
 
 
 - - ffy&k . 
 
 % *,: .-. .- *v 
 
 
 
 
 .- 
 ^ . 
 
 < UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY 
 
 * * i *" ..