7S3r 
 
 MSL3
 
 THE LIBRARY 
 
 OF 
 
 THE UNIVERSITY 
 
 OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 LOS ANGELES
 
 Series xxxvil No. 2 
 
 JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY STUDIES 
 
 IN 
 
 Historical and Political Science 
 
 Under the Direction of the 
 
 Departments of History, Political Economy, and 
 Political Science 
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND 
 
 BY 
 
 MALCOLM H. LAUCHHEIMER, PH.D. 
 First Lieutenant, Judge Advocate, A. E. F. 
 
 BALTIMORE 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 1919
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS OF BALTIMORE. 
 
 American Journal of Insanity. E. N. Bbush, J. M. Mosheb, C. M. Campbell, 
 C. K. Clabke and A. M. Baekett, Editors. Quarterly. 8vo. Volume LXXV 
 in progress. $5 per volume. (Foreign postage, fifty cents.) 
 
 American Journal of Mathematics. Edited by Pbank Moblet, with the coSpera- 
 tlon of A. Cohen, Charlotte A. Scott, A. B. Cobib and other mathema- 
 ticians. Quarterly. 4to. Volume XLI in progress. $6 per volume. (For- 
 eign postage, fifty cents.) 
 
 American Journal of Philology. Edited by B. L. Qildebsleeve and C. W. E. 
 Miller. Quarterly. 8vo. Volume XL In progress. $3 per volume. (For- 
 eign p osta ge, fifty cents.) 
 
 Beitraire zur Assyrlologrie und semitischen Sprachwissensohaft. Facl Hauft and 
 Fbiedeich Dblitzsch, Editors. Volume X in progress. 
 
 Elliott Ponographs in the Romance Languages and Literatures. E. C. Abmstbonq, 
 Editor. 8vo. $3 per year. Six numbers have appeared. 
 
 Hesperla. Hermann Collitz, Henry Wood and Jambs W. Bright, Editors. 
 8vo. Thirteen numbers have appeared. 
 
 Johns Hopkins Hospital Bulletin. Monthly. 4to. Volume XXX in progress. 
 $3 per year. (Foreign postage, fifty cents.) 
 
 Johns Hopkins Hospital Heports. 8vo. Volume XVIII in progress. $6 per volume. 
 (Foreign postage, fifty cents.) 
 
 Johns Hopkins University Circular, including the President's Report, Annual 
 Register, and Medical Department Catalogue. T. R. Ball, Editor. Monthly. 
 8vo. $1 per year. 
 
 Johns Hopkins ITniversity Studies on Education. Edited by E. F'. Buchneb 
 and C. M. Campbell. 8vo. Two numbers have appeared. 
 
 Johns Hopkins University Studies in Historical and Political Science. Under the 
 direction of the Departments of History, Political Economy, and Political 
 Science. 8vo. Volume XXXVII in progress. $3.50 per volume. 
 
 Modem Language Notes. J. W. Bright, Bditor-ln-Chlef, M. P. Brush, W. Kdr- 
 rblmeyeb and G. Gktjenbadm. Eight times yearly. 8vo. Volume XXXIV 
 In progress. $3 per volume. (Foreign postage, fifty cents.) 
 
 Beports of the Maryland Geological Survey. B. B. Mathews, Editor. 
 
 Eeprint of Economic Tracts. J. H. Hollander, Editor. Fourth series In progress. 
 $2.00. 
 
 Terrestrial Magnetism and Atmospheric Electricity. L. A. Batter, Editor. Quar- 
 terly. 8vo. Vol. XXIV in progress. ?3 per volume. (Foreign postage, 25 
 cents. ) 
 
 POBUA DB Fbrnan Goncalbz. Edited by C. Carroll Marden. 284 pp. 8vo. |2.50. 
 
 Studies in Honor of Professor Gildbbslebvb. 527 pp. 8vo. |6. 
 
 Studies in Honob of A. Mabshall Elliott. Two volumes. 8vo. 450 and 334 
 
 pp. $7.50. 
 The Hague Peace Confbbbncbs of 1899 and 1907. By James Brown Scott. 
 
 Vol. I, The Conferences, 887 pp. ; Vol. II, Documents, 548 pp. 8vo. $5. 
 The Eclogues of Baptista Mantuanus. By W. P. Mustard. 156 pp. 8vo. 
 
 $1.50, 
 The Piscatobt Eclogues of Jacopo Sannazabo. By W. P. Mustard. 94 pp. 
 
 8vo. $1, 
 Diplomatic Negotiations of Ambbican Naval Officers, 1778-1883. By C. O. 
 
 Paullin. 380 pp. 12mo. $2. 
 Four Phases of American Development — FederaZlsm, Democracy, ImperiaUtm, 
 
 Expansion. By J. B. Moore. 218 pp. 12mo. $1.50. 
 Thh Diplomacy of the War of 1812. By F. A. Updyke. 504 pp. 12mo. $2.50. 
 Earlt Diplomatic Relations between the United States and Mexico. By 
 
 W. R. Manning. 418 pp. 12mo. $2.25. 
 The West Florida Conteovbest, 1798-1813. By I. J. Cox. 710 pp. 12mo. $3. 
 An Outline of Psxchomology. By Knight Dunlap. 145 pp. 84 cuts. Royal 
 
 8vo. $2. 
 The Creed of the Old South. By B. L. Glldersleeve. 128 pp. Crown 8vt>. $1. 
 Early Diplomatic Relations between the United States and Japan*; 
 
 1853-1865. By Payson J. Treat. 468 pp. 12mo. $2.50. 
 A complete list of publications sent on request
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND
 
 Series xxxvii No. 2 
 
 JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY STUDIES 
 
 IN 
 
 Historical and Political Science 
 
 Under the Direction of the 
 
 Departments of History, Political Economy, and 
 Political Science 
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND 
 
 BY 
 
 MALCOLM H. LAUCHHEIMER, PH.D. 
 First Lieutenant, Judge Advocate, A. E. F. 
 
 BALTIMORE 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 19x9
 
 Copyright 1919 by 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 PRESS OF 
 
 THE NEW ERA PRINTING COMPANY 
 
 LANCASTER. PA.
 
 7^35" 
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 Pags 
 
 PREFACE vii 
 
 CHAPTER I. Introduction 9 
 
 The Problem of the Labor Law 9 
 
 Maryland Conditions '6 
 
 CHAPTER n. The Labor Union 19 
 
 The Law of Union Activities *9 
 
 Statutes Relating to Unionism 39 
 
 CHAPTER in. The Workmen's Compensation Law 46 
 
 History 46 
 
 The Present Law as Social Legislation 5 ^ 
 
 The Constitutionality of the Law 7° 
 
 CHAPTER IV. The Conditions of Employment 76 
 
 Regulation by Commission 77 
 
 Fire Protection ^* 
 
 Protective Devices ^5 
 
 Sanitation 86 
 
 The Tenement Law 9° 
 
 CHAPTER V. The Terms of Employment 94 
 
 Foreword 94 
 
 Prohibitions of EmplojTnent 96 
 
 Hours 100 
 
 Wages 104 
 
 CHAPTER VL Some Miscellaneous Laws "3 
 
 Licenses . .* ^ *3 
 
 Attachments and Liens "^ 
 
 Child Welfare "7 
 
 State Employment ^^9 
 
 CHAPTER Vn. The Administrative System 122 
 
 State Board of Labor and Statistics '23 
 
 State Board of Health ^3S 
 
 Minor Administrative Agencies '35 
 
 Suggestions for Reform '3° 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. The State in Relation to Labor MS 
 
 V 
 
 N 
 
 G9Gi30 
 
 INST. INBUS. KBL.
 
 PREFACE 
 
 This monograph needs little preface. The method of 
 study is local and intensive, but I have endeavored to draw 
 some general conclusions from the specific subject-matter 
 treated. The book, as its title implies, is neither a text 
 book nor a reference book, though it may serve to a slight 
 degree in the latter capacity, but a dissertation. 
 
 I take this means of expressing my gratitude to Prof. 
 W. W. Willoughby, who served as my inspiration and 
 rendered me much assistance in the preparation of this 
 monograph, and also to Prof. George E. Barnett and to 
 Miss Anna Herkner, former Assistant-Chief of the Mary- 
 land Bureau of Statistics. Various others to whom I am 
 indebted are mentioned throughout the text. 
 
 The monograph was completed towards the end of 1916 
 and, because of the author's participation in the war, it has 
 been impossible to bring it up to date in many particulars. 
 
 M. H. L. 
 
 Til
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND 
 
 CHAPTER I 
 
 Introduction 
 
 The Problem of the Labor Law. — The labor law of a 
 state is a peculiar combination of unwritten and statute 
 law. It differs from most law in that it is not merely an 
 evolution of the customary law of a community, but is a 
 definite attempt by the community to solve, now by the 
 common law, now by statute, an acute social problem. It 
 does to a degree reflect the customary morality of the com- 
 munity, but this not unconsciously, as, for example, in the 
 case of commercial law, but as a conscious adoption of an 
 ethical principle for a political norm. A complete under- 
 standing of labor law requires, therefore, not merely a 
 delving into jurisprudence, but also into political the- 
 ory. We must study, not merely the law itself, but the 
 law as an expression of the relation of the state to its citi- 
 zens; the labor law in truth is one of the most interesting 
 media in which to study the extent to which the state can 
 justify its interference in the private life of individuals. 
 Accordingly, although this study will be primarily a critical 
 analysis and description of actual laws in practical opera- 
 tion, there will necessarily be in it an undercurrent of specu- 
 lative political theory. 
 
 The state, then, in its labor law sets out to solve a very 
 definite social problem, the problem of industrial unrest, 
 the problem of reconciling and placating labor and capital. 
 The history of this activity of the state stretches back six 
 or seven centuries, and the policy of the state has varied 
 from complete aloofness to intimate intervention. 
 
 9
 
 10 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [156 
 
 Logically and perhaps historically the first instrumental- 
 ity made use of by the state in meeting the labor problem 
 is the common law. This results, not from an active in- 
 tent on the part of the state to solve any problem, but from 
 a quiescent attitude towards an unimportant phenomenon. 
 The common law is turned to before the labor problem 
 assumes any special characteristics of its own, and the 
 various cases are settled according to the general principles 
 of the common law as laid down in cases between individ- 
 uals who are in no special relation to each other. If, in the 
 beginning, as is usually the case, no economic question 
 obtrudes into the case, but the matter is one of pure law, 
 the decision based on former precedents will work substan- 
 tial justice. When, on the other hand, the relative economic 
 position of the two parties is of importance, decisions based 
 on pure law will not be adequate and will often entirely 
 fail to settle the question at bar. When, as always hap- 
 pens, the economic status of the parties does not merit 
 attention until after the deciding of cases involving similar 
 matters, but not calling into question the economic relation, 
 it is practically impossible for the judges when the economic 
 question is presented to them to disregard the precedents 
 and to dispense economic justice and not justice according 
 to law. Common law does, as is often said, progress and 
 grow with the times, but more often legislation is necessary 
 to make it entirely adequate. Thus the common law of 
 negligence did not meet the requirements of industrial 
 accidents, and employers' liability and compensation laws 
 were the result. Thus the common law of individual bar- 
 gaining and competition does not seem to meet the require- 
 ments of collective bargaining, and legislation recognizing 
 the validity of unionism is being demanded. 
 
 A more serious inadequacy of the common law, how- 
 ever, as a means of solving the labor problem arises from 
 the inherent characteristic of that law as a system of juris- 
 prudence. The common law is remedial, compensatory; 
 labor conditions call for regulation, prohibition. The com-
 
 157] INTRODUCTION II 
 
 mon law seeks to relieve the sting of a wrong after it has 
 been committed ; labor conditions necessitate regulations 
 making impossible the commission of the wrong. A close 
 scrutiny of the entire field of the common law will reveal 
 no principles which could support such movements as the 
 " safety first " and " living wage " propagandas. Even 
 equity with its canons of preventive relief against irrepara- 
 ble injuries does not furnish a proper foundation for the 
 state control of labor conditions. Thus, though the state 
 could and does depend to a great degree upon its unwritten 
 law in solving the economic problem of labor and capital, 
 it must and does every day more and more seek the answer 
 in social legislation. 
 
 But the first manifestations of state activity in the field 
 of labor legislation were of an entirely different nature 
 from what is now usually referred to as social legislation. 
 These laws, of which the Statute of Laborers, passed after 
 the Black Death, with its later variations and the Eliza- 
 bethan Statute of Apprentices are the classical examples, 
 were not based upon any economic principle of the welfare 
 of the laborer, but, in so far as any general principle of 
 economics was involved, upon a desire to keep low the cost 
 of commodities. Rather, it may be said, these laws were 
 secured by the dominant legislative class, the monied class, 
 for its own immediate benefit. In this sense these laws, 
 like most labor laws, were class legislation and nothing else. 
 But there did develop under the name of mercantilism, 
 of which these two laws were precursors, a theory of state 
 activity which entirely neglected the interests of the work- 
 ingman. Under this system the paternalistic state in its 
 endeavor to develop itself through its commerce subordi- 
 nated the laborer to the merchant and subjected him to 
 minute control in many of the terms of his employment. 
 It is, of course, true that the workingman whom this legis- 
 lation affected had just emerged from the status of serf- 
 dom and was a new and disturbing factor in the industrial 
 life of the time. But so thorough was this repressive legis-
 
 12 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [158 
 
 lation that the new, free laborer was hardly in a better 
 position than the former villein. 
 
 It was against this system that Adam Smith and Jeremy 
 Bentham wrote; and as a result of their preachings there 
 ensued the period of laissez-faire in the relation of the 
 state to labor. At the climax of this individualistic philoso- 
 phy the state retired almost completely from the regulation 
 of economic affairs. Competition was relied upon to work 
 the salvation of society. The individual laborer was made 
 perfectly free to bargain for his own terms and to secure 
 his own economic betterment. The state progressed 
 through the progress of its individual citizens. 
 
 The period of laissez-faire marked a real and substan- 
 tial advance for the workingman, but it was short-lived. It 
 was not any inherent fallacies in the theory which caused 
 its modification — the philosophy of individualism has never 
 been abandoned — but rather a change in the actual condi- 
 tions to which the theory had to be applied. Contempora- 
 neously with the growth of laissez-faire individualism OC' 
 curred that stupendous advance in industrialism which is 
 usually termed the Industrial Revolution. With the inven- 
 tion of steam-driven machines and modern means of trans- 
 portation the factory system of manufacture speedily took 
 the place of the small shop system. A single employer 
 began to employ hundreds and then thousands of laborers. 
 The laborer, though legally and theoretically free to bar- 
 gain with the employer for the terms of his employment, 
 found himself practically at such a disadvantage that the 
 employer could hire him almost on his own terms. The 
 labor union was the workingman's answer to the factory 
 system, but it has not yet proved adequate in itself. The 
 state has, therefore, stepped in to guarantee to the laborer 
 certain terms and conditions of employment which have 
 been conceived to be reasonable and necessary. 
 
 This is the present-day status of labor legislation. The 
 doctrine of laissez-faire survives in so far as the state 
 leaves to the common law and individual action all that 
 
 /
 
 159] I NTRODUCTION 1 3 
 
 these instrumentalities are capable of handling. Laissez- 
 faire is abandoned in so far as the state, recognizing the 
 inequality of the bargaining power of employer and em- 
 ployee, regulates as seems best for the welfare of the state 
 certain of the terms of the bargain. The state sacrifices 
 theoretical individual liberty for what is considered a truer 
 means of self-development. The state in its endeavor to 
 offset this inequality of bargaining power has returned to 
 some of the functions of the medieval paternalistic state; 
 but those who wish to make the distinction between the 
 former antagonistic and the present sympathetic attitude of 
 the state to labor sometimes term the present state mater- 
 nalistic rather than paternalistic in its regulations. To a 
 certain degree this distinction is specious and more will be 
 said of it in the final chapter of this study. It is sufficient 
 to say here that the solution which has been attained in 
 practical legislation is hardly a final remedy. 
 
 In the United States there is, besides political theoriz- 
 ing upon the relation of the state to labor, another funda- 
 mental to be considered. Our written constitutions en- 
 forced by powerful courts impose a legal limitation upon 
 state activity as well as a philosophical limitation. While 
 the state is quiescent the constitution is unobtrusive; but 
 when the state functions in enacting laws the constitution 
 exercises a tremendous restraint upon state action. The 
 whole of state activity in the United States affecting the 
 labor problem has been manifested within the last of the 
 periods just discussed, that of laissez-faire ameliorated in 
 favor of the laborer. All of this social legislation comes in 
 conflict with the " equal protection of the laws " and the 
 "due process of law" clauses of the Fourteenth Amend- 
 ment of the federal constitution or similar provisions of the 
 state constitutions. Both require brief discussion. 
 
 The essentials of " equal protection of the laws " are eas- 
 ily stated. Every citizen of a state is entitled to equal treat- 
 ment by the laws of that jurisdiction and to all the privi- 
 leges extended to any other citizen by the law. Reasonable
 
 14 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l6o 
 
 classification, however, is permissible if exercised on ad- 
 ministrative or any other justifiable grounds. Legislative 
 classifications are prima facie reasonable. 
 
 The "due process of law" clause is not so easily ex- 
 plained. Historically it is traced back to the per legem 
 terrae provision of Magna Charta, but as a substantive 
 provision of law its development is recent. Strictly con- 
 ceived this clause might have been construed as making 
 perpetual the eighteenth century doctrines of laissez-faire 
 and natural rights, and as limiting state activity to the nar- 
 rowest bounds. The clause luckily never received so nar- 
 rowing an interpretation, but was merely construed as 
 allowing the courts to inquire whether property appropri- 
 ated by legislation was taken for a legitimate state purpose. 
 Early in their interpretation of this clause, especially with 
 reference to social legislation, the courts evolved the police 
 power of the state as an exception to the prohibition and 
 through this exception the effect of the prohibition has been 
 much curtailed. It is indeed more profitable to consider 
 the cases dealing with labor legislation under the Fourteenth 
 Amendment as limiting the extent of the police power than 
 as defining due process of law, for the exercise of the police 
 power is due process of law. 
 
 Thus viewed, the explanation becomes more simple. It 
 is still impossible to define and limit exactly the police 
 power, but it is now possible to give rather succinctly the 
 two extreme views to one of which most decisions adhere. 
 There is, on the one hand, the strict legalistic view that the 
 police power extends only to the protection of the health, 
 safety and morals of the community ; that the state activity 
 should be strictly defined ; that none but the most moderate 
 of social legislation should be enacted. The Maryland 
 Court of Appeals leans to this view, although it is not en- 
 tirely constant in its principles. The other view is that the 
 police power extends also to the furtherance of public con- 
 venience. As put by Justice Holmes, "it may be said in 
 a general way that the police power extends to all the great
 
 l6l] INTRODUCTION 1 5 
 
 public needs. It may be put forth in aid of what is sanc- 
 tioned by usage, or held by the prevailing morality or 
 strong and preponderant opinion to be greatly and imme- 
 diately necessary to the public welfare."^ This is the view 
 held by the Supreme Court and appears to exercise practi- 
 cally no restraint on really seriously considered legislation.* 
 Having these fundamentals in view, even as so inade- 
 quately outlined in this chapter, the object and plan of this 
 study may be made clear. The primary purpose has been 
 to describe and analyze all of the law of Maryland in any 
 way concerning labor. In order better to understand the 
 law of Maryland, I have usually brought it into contrast 
 or comparison with some conceived ideal borrowed some- 
 times from purely theoretical sources, but more often from 
 the law of other communities, generally of other States of 
 the Union such as Massachusetts, New York and Wiscon- 
 sin, but when necessary going to England and Continental 
 Europe for suggestions. In fulfilling this primary purpose 
 there must usually be some incidental consideration of the 
 manner in which Maryland has met the problems which 
 have just been outlined. This discussion of political theory 
 will be kept strictly in the backgroimd until the last chap- 
 ter, which will endeavor to lay down some constructive 
 principles. The plan of the work has been to follow as 
 ,closely as possible the logical development of state activity. 
 No space has been allotted to the consideration of the law 
 of the labor contract, since this law is merely an adaptation 
 of ordinary contract law and contains no distinctive feat- 
 ures. The study begins with the law of the labor union, 
 which has been almost entirely left to the common law. 
 Then follows a consideration of the law of workmen's com- 
 pensation, which marks the only complete abandonment of 
 any principles of the common law referring to labor. The 
 three succeeding chapters deal with the new social legis- 
 
 1 Noble State Bank v. Haskell, 219 U. S. 104. 
 
 2 For a statement of the author's sympathy with this view, see his 
 article, "Imminent Constitutional Shams," in the Forum, vol. 57. 
 Jan. 1917, pp. 91-98.
 
 1 6 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l62 
 
 lation, demonstrating how far the laissez-faire theory has 
 been abandoned; and the study ends with chapters on the 
 administrative system and the relation of the state to labor. 
 But before taking up the law itself it is necessary to set 
 forth some uninteresting, but necessary, facts about Mary- 
 land. 
 
 Maryland Conditions. — As far as labor law is concerned 
 Maryland will be found to be, if not a typical American 
 State — for no State is typical when legislation is in question 
 — at least a mean or average State. Its law displays none 
 of the extremist characteristics of the experimentally in- 
 clined Western and Middle Western States, nor does it lag 
 with the Southern States in the wake of social legislation. 
 It follows rather closely on the heels of New York and 
 more remotely after the more radical Massachusetts. Con- 
 sidering its geographical position Maryland, with its some- 
 what backward labor law, may be judged rather leniently. 
 
 The State is usually classed as one of the Southern States. 
 Though the northernmost of these States and outside of the 
 Confederacy in the Civil War, it was a slave State and had 
 all the traditions of the aristocratic, non-industrial South. 
 Moreover its southern neighbors, Virginia and West Vir- 
 ginia, have the typical Southern labor law, perhaps suffi- 
 cient for their needs, but by no means effective. On the 
 other hand, Maryland has come to be in the class of indus- 
 trial States and, in this respect, her competitors lie to the 
 north rather than to the south. But, here also, the State 
 is restrained rather than spurred on by its neighbors. 
 Pennsylvania, which borders the whole northern boundary, 
 has until recently been most delinquent in its labor law and 
 many of the odious half measures in the Maryland law 
 have been caused by the potential competition of Pennsyl- 
 vania's industries. These excuses for the inferiority of the 
 Maryland law call up an explanation of another cause of 
 Maryland's backwardness. Like most Southern States, 
 Maryland's party politics are at a low ebb. The State 
 does not seem to have mastered the art of clean politics and
 
 163] INTRODUCTION 1 7 
 
 it is dominated much more than is desirable by mediocre 
 poHticians. Ahhough this condition does not perhaps ac- 
 count for many statutory shortcomings, its effect is evi- 
 dent in the administration of the law. 
 
 Aside from these external facts, there are other practi- 
 cal difficulties which must be mastered in solving by legis- 
 lation the labor problem. The population of Maryland in 
 1910 was 1,295,346, about evenly divided between urban 
 and rural. Of the urban population, however, 558,485 
 people are collected in Baltimore City, which is the only 
 city of any size in the State. There are besides Baltimore 
 three other cities of between ten and twenty-five thousand 
 population and eleven other towns which are classified as 
 urban. Baltimore is, therefore, practically the only large 
 industrial center in the State and in it alone are found 
 many of the social problems which are usually the occasion 
 of legislation. Maryland, furthermore, is divided into two 
 unequal parts by the Chesapeake Bay. The Eastern Shore, 
 with a population of 200,161, is almost entirely rural and 
 the only industry of any importance is canning, which for 
 political as well as administrative reasons is almost unregu- 
 lated. The Western Shore may again be divided into tw'O 
 sections, the Western Shore proper and Western Maryland. 
 In the first of these is Baltimore, w^hich practically domi- 
 nates the industrial life of the section. Western Maryland 
 lies in the Appalachians and centers around Cumberland, 
 the second largest city in the State. Its chief industries are 
 coal-mining and transportation. Western Maryland is a 
 narrow strip of country, and it is chiefly here that the low 
 standards of the Pennsylvania and West Virginia labor 
 laws have to be guarded against. Geographical and eco- 
 nomic sectionalism accounts for the great amount of local 
 legislation on the Maryland statute books and to some ex- 
 tent for the lack of coordination in the administrative 
 system. 
 
 In 1910 there were employed in gainful occupations a
 
 1 8 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [164 
 
 total of 541,164 persons, of whom 410,884 were male and 
 130,280 were female, comprising, respectively, 81 per cent 
 and 25 per cent of the total population of each sex above 
 the age of ten years. Their occupational distribution was 
 as follows: 
 
 Occupation Number Per Cent 
 
 Agriculture 171,100 21.6 
 
 Manufacture 172,155 31.8 
 
 Domestic and personal service 78,820 14.6 
 
 Trade 61,646 11.4 
 
 Transportation ^^,77^ 7.9 
 
 Clerical 28,871 5.3 
 
 Professional 23,474 4.3 
 
 Public service 8,954 1.7 
 
 Mining 7,368 1.4
 
 CHAPTER II 
 The Labor Union 
 
 The Law of Union Activities. — Historically the law of 
 labor union activities was the first evolved by the state; 
 evolved, not enacted, for most of it is judge-made law. 
 Logically considered, also, the law of union activities must 
 be accorded first place; for, granted that the labor union 
 receives favorable treatment from the state, it seems easy 
 to demonstrate that hardly any other state activity is neces- 
 sary. 
 
 The Maryland labor law of the present day is based on 
 and grew from the eafly English law, and hence some slight 
 treatment of that law is necessary. The beginnings of the 
 English law, however, are somewhat surrounded in mys- 
 tery. It seems that the earliest activities of the union were 
 branded as criminal conspiracy at the common law, though 
 it is by no means certain that the ofifense of criminal con- 
 spiracy was not the creation of a statute. Be this as it may, 
 before labor unions as such came into prominence statutes 
 were passed early in the eighteenth century forbidding com- 
 binations of laborers for the raising of wages and other 
 purposes and making such combinations criminal conspira- 
 cies. These statutes grew in severity and comprehensive- 
 ness until the beginning of the nineteenth century. There- 
 after the law became more liberal. The cause of this change 
 was the union itself. Utterly unsanctioned and potentially 
 oppressed in its most beneficial activities by the law, it nev- 
 ertheless continued to exist. It was not a casual phenome- 
 non: it was an economic growth, necessary to and justified 
 by industrial conditions. Slowly and often surreptitiously 
 it grew, but grow it did until, in the atmosphere of greater 
 political liberty, it made itself felt in legislative halls. In 
 
 19
 
 20 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l66 
 
 1875 the ban of criminal conspiracy was lifted and finally, 
 in 1906, the union was granted a most enviable place in 
 English law.^ 
 
 Maryland in 1776 adopted, with the other twelve States, 
 the English law of union activities in so far as it was con- 
 sonant with American ideas and ideals. This law was the 
 harsh, antagonistic law of the eighteenth century hardly 
 modified at all in the adoption. Thus, in an early case, the 
 Maryland Court of Appeals sums up the law of criminal 
 conspiracy: "An indictment will lie at common law — (i) 
 for a conspiracy to do an act not illegal, nor punishable if 
 done by an individual, but immoral only; (2) for a con- 
 spiracy to do an act neither illegal nor immoral in an indi- 
 vidual, but to effect a purpose which has a tendency to 
 prejudice the public — for a conspiracy (by two or more) 
 to raise their wages, either of whom might legally have 
 done so; (3) for a conspiracy to extort money from an- 
 other, or to injure his reputation by means not indictable if 
 practised by an individual, as by verbal defamation ; (4) 
 for a conspiracy to cheat and defraud a third person, ac- 
 complished by means of an act which would not in law 
 amount to an indictable cheat if effected by an individual ; 
 (5) for a malicious conspiracy to impoverish or ruin a third 
 person in his trade or profession; (6) for a conspiracy to 
 defraud a third person by means of an act not per se un- 
 lawful and though no person be thereby injured; (7) for 
 a bare conspiracy to cheat or defraud a third person, though 
 the means of effecting it should not be determined on at 
 the time."- It is obvious that, either under the third clause 
 declaring indictable a conspiracy to raise wages or under 
 the fifth referring to a conspiracy "to impoverish or ruin 
 a third person in his trade or profession," a labor union 
 would almost surely have found itself running counter to 
 the law. In fact, if the union were merely formed for one 
 
 1 For a complete discussion of the early law of conspiracy as 
 applied to labor unions, see J. W. Bryan, English Law of Conspiracy. 
 
 2 State V. Buchanan, 5 H. & J. 317 (1821).
 
 167] THE LABOR UNION 21 
 
 of these purposes — and it must be remembered that these 
 prohibitions against conspiracy referred to the indirect 
 effects as well as to the direct purposes of the union — it 
 would be absolutely barred ; for, in the same case, the court 
 declared : " A conspiracy is a substantive offence and pun- 
 ishable at common law, though nothing be done in execu- 
 tion of it." It seems, indeed, that this decision was entirely 
 efficient, for no cases concerning trade unions came before 
 the Appeal Court under this decision. But it must not be 
 imagined that merely because no cases against unions came 
 before the court there were no unions. The decision was 
 efficient and complete, but hardly effective. As in England, 
 trade unions seem to have flourished even under the shadow 
 of the law and to have carried on trade disputes, perhaps 
 not legally, but extra-legally. 
 
 It was probably because of the growing strength of the 
 unions, especially as political institutions, that the legisla- 
 ture of 1884 was compelled to recognize their existence. In 
 that year two bills were enacted legalizing labor unions. 
 The first declared that an act of a combination formed in 
 " furtherance of a trade dispute between employers and 
 workmen shall not be indictable as a conspiracy, if such act 
 committed by one person would not be punishable as an 
 offense (nothing in this section shall affect the law relat- 
 ing to riot, unlawful assembly, breach of peace, or any 
 offense against any person or against property)."^ The 
 second was an addition to the incorporation acts, permit- 
 ting the incorporation of trade unions " to promote the 
 well-being of their every day life, and for mutual assistance 
 in securing the most favorable conditions for the labor of 
 their members."* In this year, then, we can say, the labor 
 union entered the realm of law in Maryland. In this year, 
 also, the law concerning unionism took a different turn. 
 Prior to this the unions had been subject to the law of 
 
 3 Laws 1884, Ch. 266; Code 1914, Art. 2^, Sec. 40. 
 
 *Laws 1884, Ch. 267; Code 1904, Art. 23, Sec. 41. Incorporation 
 since 1908 takes place under the general law of incorporation, Laws 
 1908, Ch. 240, Sees. 2-5; Code 1911, Art. 23, Sees. 2-5.
 
 22 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l68 
 
 criminal conspiracy; after these acts the employers were 
 able to combat the unions in court merely by civil suits or 
 injunctions. Prior to this year, moreover, no cases involv- 
 ing unionism came before the Court of Appeals, so that the 
 Maryland law, in contradistinction to the English law, has 
 practically nothing to do with criminal conspiracy. 
 
 The salient principle in the Maryland law of labor unions 
 — and indeed in all American law on this subject — is the 
 right of the individual to his own property and, what is 
 practically identical in law, the right to freedom of contract. 
 There has also been evolved another right, sometimes con- 
 sidered a property right, the right to carry on one's busi- 
 ness or to work at one's trade free from outside interfer- 
 ence. This right is indeed a recent creation of the courts, 
 and, to a certain degree, an unfortunate creation. It is 
 broader than the right of personal freedom and was, there- 
 fore, useful in ruling against some of the first harsh, but 
 elusive, activities of the union; but there are two sides to 
 this right and the unions soon came to assert it on their 
 side. There are in every conflict between union and em- 
 ployer two conflicting rights. A strike is called for an in- 
 crease in wages or for shorter hours, what the employees 
 conceive to be their rights ; the employer forthwith asserts 
 that his freedom of contract is being abridged. A labor 
 union stipulates that its men shall work only in a " closed 
 shop," and the discharged non-union man sues for a viola- 
 tion of his right to work as he will. To generalize briefly 
 in advance, we shall find in considering strikes, boycotts, 
 closed shops — in short, all of the means by which a union 
 makes its demands effective — that "honest effort to better 
 the conditions of employment by the members of a labor 
 union is lawful,"^ though it may incidentally interfere with 
 the right of an individual to work on such terms as he may 
 see fit. If, however, the aim of the union is wilful inter- 
 ference with the individual, though the union may thereby 
 be indirectly benefited, the union is operating contrary to 
 
 5 Minasian v. Osborne, 210 Mass. 250, 96 N. E. 1036 (1912).
 
 169] THE LABOR UNION 2$ 
 
 the law. Let us first, however, consider in some detail the 
 law relating to the various activities of the unions. 
 
 "The right to organize and to utilize their organization 
 by instituting a strike is an exercise of the common law 
 right of every man to pursue his calling, whether of labor 
 or business, as he in his judgment sees fit."*^ A strike per 
 se is not unlawful ; it is the purpose'' or the means® which 
 renders it unlawful. " The law does not permit either em- 
 ployer or employee to use force, violence, threats of force 
 or threats of violence, intimidation or coercion,"^ so that it 
 may be said now and for all that force is unlawful ; and, 
 for the sake of brevity, the consideration of violence may 
 be dismissed from the following discussion. 
 
 The leading Maryland case on labor organizations is the 
 case of My Maryland Lodge v. Adt,^*^ and it will be best 
 to quote first from that part of the decision relating to 
 strikes. " Employees have a perfect right," says the court, 
 " both as individuals and in combination, to fix a price upon 
 their labor, and to refuse to work unless that price is ob- 
 tained. They may organize to improve their condition and 
 to secure better wages. They may even use persuasion to 
 have others join their organization. They have an unques- 
 tionable right to present their cause to the public in news- 
 papers or circulars in a peaceable way, but with no attempt 
 at coercion. If ruin to the employer results from their 
 peaceable assertion of these rights, it is a damage without 
 remedy." Laborers, therefore, may strike for an increase 
 of wages, for shorter hours, for better working conditions, 
 for specified methods of employment or of pay.^^ They 
 
 « Martin, Modern Law of Labor Unions, p. 36. 
 
 7 Reynolds v. Davis, 198 Mass. 294, 84 N. E. 457. 
 
 8 My Maryland Lodge v. Adt, 100 Md. 283, 68 L. R. A. 152. 
 e Ibid. 
 
 " Ibid. 
 
 11 It has even been held in a federal court (Delaware, L. & W. 
 R. R. Co. vs. Switchmen's Union, 158 Fed. 541) that workmen may 
 strike for such purposes even though it be in violation of their 
 service contract. What the court' very probably meant was that 
 these strikers could not be enjoined; they are clearly liable for 
 damages.
 
 24 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l?© 
 
 may, it has been held, even seek the aid of their fellow 
 workers in another establishment to join with them in a 
 sympathetic strike if the employer is striving to circumvent 
 the efforts of the strikers by having his work done in brother 
 employers' shops/- But this case, although well considered 
 and precise, must be confined to the exact point involved; 
 for a sympathetic strike, like a secondary boycott, usually 
 brings into the contest an uninterested third person who, if 
 injured, usually has a cause of action against the union. 
 Where there is such a community of interest as in this case, 
 however, a sympathetic strike is not actionable. Another 
 danger which must be avoided by the sympathetic strike as 
 well as by all other union activities is the possibility that 
 the union may be running counter to the contract liabilities 
 of a third party, for " a man who induces one of two par- 
 ties to a contract to break it, intending thereby to injure the 
 other or obtain a benefit for himself, does the other an 
 actionable wrong."^^ This is a fundamental rule of con- 
 tract law and has no special application to the law of the 
 labor union : it is mentioned here merely because of the num- 
 ber of times the union has felt its force/* 
 
 The foregoing conclusions that a strike is a legal instru- 
 ment of the labor tmion apply only when the disputes ars 
 strictly limited to the two parties concerned, the strikers 
 and their employer ; when a third party suffers injury, as 
 was intimated in discussing the sympathetic strike, the 
 strike stands in less favor with the courts. Unfortunately 
 it is a rare strike which does not directly or indirectly affect 
 some third person. The cause of this can readily be seen 
 if we consider the problem from the point of view of the 
 unions. The strike cannot be effective if the employer is 
 able to fill easily the places of the strikers with non-union 
 
 12 Iron Moulders' Union v. Allis-Chambers Co., i66 Fed. 45 ; 20 
 L. R. A. (N. S.) 315. 
 
 13 Gore V. Condon, 87 Md. 368, 376. 
 
 1* A few of these cases only are here cited : Garst v. Charles, 187 
 Mass. 144; Folsom v. Lewis, 208 Mass. 336; Iron Moulders' Union 
 V. Allis-Chambers Co., 166 Fed. 45.
 
 I/l] THE LABOR UNION 2$ 
 
 men. The unions strive to prevent this by picketing and by 
 making the union monopoHstic as to that particular class of 
 workmen. Again, the strike will not attain the maximum 
 efficiency if the standard which is obtained by the union is 
 continually undermined by the cut-throat competition of 
 non-union men in the same shop. The unions fight against 
 this evil with the instrument of the closed shop. Again, the 
 strike will often fail entirely if other employers or dealers 
 trade in their normal manner with the tabooed employer. 
 To offset this, the union has evolved the boycott, or more 
 correctly in the technical economic phrase, the secondary 
 boycott. But, before considering any of these more ad- 
 vanced forms of union activity, it will be first necessary to 
 consider one more form of strike, a rather more advanced 
 and more involved form of this particular activity which 
 might be called a cross between the strike and the closed 
 shop. It is a strike, not to procure an immediate advantage, 
 as, for example, a raise of wages, but to strengthen the 
 union by dictating to the employer certain terms of employ- 
 ment for all men in his shop. A Maryland case will illus- 
 trate. 
 
 In Lucke v. Clothing Cutters' Assembly^^ the appellant, 
 a non-union man, had had permanent employment termin- 
 able at will with the New York Clothing House. He was 
 objected to by the appellee, who notified the clothing house 
 that they objected to working with non-union men. Lucke 
 applied for membership in the union ; but, because of the 
 lack of employment among its then members, the appellee 
 refused him membership. Later the union sent notice to 
 the employer that, if Lucke were not discharged, it would 
 notify through its official organ all labor organizations of 
 the city that "the house was a non-union one." Feeling 
 that it was threatened with a boycott, though during the 
 trial the union denied that this was its intention, the New 
 York Clothing House discharged the appellant, who later 
 
 ^^yy Md. 396; 19 L. R. A. 408 (1893).
 
 26 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [172 
 
 brought suit against the union for damages. The court held 
 that Lucke was entitled to damages since the union had in- 
 terfered with his right of property and freedom of contract. 
 This interference may have indirectly benefited the union, 
 but it wilfully and directly injured the individual in one of 
 his fundamental rights ; and the court said : 
 
 " It is not necessary that such interference [of the union 
 with a laboring man's privilege of seeking an honest liveli- 
 hood] should have been malicious in its character. ... In 
 this case we think the interference of the appellee was in 
 law malicious and unquestionably wrongful . . . and, by so 
 doing, it [the appellee] has invaded legal rights of the ap- 
 pellant for which an action properly lies. 
 
 "When the state granted its generous sanction to the 
 formation of corporations of the character of the appellee 
 (Code 1904, Art. 23, Sec. 37) it certainly did not mean 
 that such promotion (of the well-being of their every day 
 life and for mutual assistance in securing the most favor- 
 able conditions for the labor of their members) was to be 
 secured by making war upon the non-union laboring man, 
 or by any legal interference with his rights and privileges. 
 The powers with which this class of corporations are 
 clothed are of a peculiar character, and should be used with 
 prudence, moderation and wisdom, so that labor in its or- 
 ganized form shall not become an instrument of wrong and 
 injustice to those who, in the same avenue of life, and some- 
 times under less favorable circumstances, are striving to 
 provide the means by which they can maintain themselves 
 and their famihes." 
 
 To understand more thoroughly the significance of this 
 case let us look at one apparently opposed to it, that of 
 Pickett V. Walsh," in which was held legal a strike to en- 
 force an agreement between a bricklayers' union and a con- 
 tractor, by which the union agreed to work for the contrac- 
 tor if he would employ its members to perform some tasks 
 
 16 192 Mass. 572; 78 N. E. 753; 6 L. R. A. (N. S.) 1067 (1907).
 
 173] '^^^ LABOR UNION 2/ 
 
 closely allied to, but less skilled than bricklaying. The 
 court differentiated between these two cases on the ground 
 that the strike in the latter case was on a matter directly 
 concerning the two parties to it, the strikers and the em- 
 ployers, and that the laborers were striving directly to im- 
 prove their own conditions. This distinction seems to have 
 been generally followed," but in discussing this question 
 some of the finest legal reasoning has been used. The 
 tendency seems to be to find a community of interest among 
 the strikers and between them and their brother unionists 
 who are not actively engaged in the strike, but for whose 
 benefit the strike is declared, and, on the whole, the trend 
 seems to be towards holding legal strikes aimed at securing 
 these competitive advantages for union laborers. The dis- 
 tinction, however, is still good between mediate and imme- 
 diate quarrels and will certainly be used in hard cases where 
 justice seems to demand it.^® 
 
 If the tendency has been towards increasing the rights 
 and powers of trade unions in securing the privileged em- 
 ployment of its own members, the absolute contrary has 
 been true with respect to the legality of picketing. Labor 
 unions, in fact, have suffered to a great degree because of 
 of injunctions restraining them from posting members on 
 the environs of the place of strike to persuade strike- 
 breakers not to take employment in the hostile shop and 
 to obtain information as to the employer's activities. Pick- 
 eting, it is true, was far from being such a milk-and-water 
 affair twenty-five years ago as it is now ; it was in this ac- 
 tivity, perhaps, that the trade unions showed their ugliest 
 side and incurred the ill-will of the public. This popular 
 estimate seems to have been reflected to a great degree in 
 the courts, which, beginning by merely discountenancing 
 picketing that was contrary to public order, have come to 
 
 1' E. g., National Fireproofing Co. v. Mason Builders' Ass'n, 169 
 Fed. 256, 26 L. R. A. (N. S.) 148; and Meur v. Speer, 32 L. R. A. 
 (N. S.) 792 (Ark.). 
 
 18 For a fuller discussion see note in 6 L. R. A. (N. S.) 1067.
 
 28 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND ['74 
 
 look Upon almost all picketing as enjoinable, if not abso- 
 lutely criminal. 
 
 A general declaration of the law was given in the case of 
 My Maryland Lodge v. Adt:^** "They (the union laborers) 
 may even use persuasion to have others join their organiza- 
 tion.^^ They have an unquestionable right to present their 
 cause to the public in newspapers or circulars in a peace- 
 able way. , . . But the law does not permit either employer 
 or employee to use force, violence, threats of force or 
 threats of violence, intimidation or coercion." The trouble- 
 some question has been, what is intimidation and coercion? 
 Thus mere argument, where the odds were four or five to 
 one in favor of the arguers, has been said to constitute un- 
 lawful intimidation. 2^ Peaceful picketing, which inci- 
 dentally interfered with customers patronizing the picketed 
 shop, has been enjoined.-^ A fair statement of the law is 
 contained in the following : " The very fact of establishing 
 a picket line is evidence of an intention to annoy, embar- 
 rass and intimidate, whether physical violence is resorted 
 to or not. There have been a few cases where it was held 
 that picketing by a labor union is not unnecessarily unlaw- 
 ful if the pickets are peaceful and well behaved ; but, if the 
 watching and besetting of the workmen is carried to such 
 a length as to constitute an annoyance to them or their em- 
 ployed, it becomes unlawful. ... To picket . . . was in 
 itself an act of intimidation and an unwarrantable interfer- 
 ence with the employer's rights." Even if pickets are not 
 guilty of intimidation, " the complainants are entitled to pro- 
 tection."^^ The Maryland law would seem to go quite as 
 far as this Illinois case, for, in spite of the rather liberal 
 language just quoted from the Adt case, the court in that 
 
 19 loo Md. 283 ; 68 L. R. A. 752- 
 
 20 See, however, Hitchman Coal & Coke Co. v. Mitchell et al., 38 
 Sup. Ct. 65 (1917). 
 
 21 Allis-Chambers Co. v. Iron Moulders' Union, 150 Fed. 155. 
 
 22 Foster v. Retail Clerks' Intern'tl Protective Ass'n, 78 N. Y. S. 
 860. 
 
 23 Barnes v. Chicago Typographical Union, 232 111. 421 ; 14 L. R. 
 A. (N. S.) 1018.
 
 1/5] THE LABOR UNION 29 
 
 case upheld an injunction which practically forbade all 
 picketing, even for purposes of information only. It would 
 then seem that picketing has been in law practically plucked 
 of its stings : picketing can perhaps be safely used only as 
 a means of procuring information. This would indeed be 
 a hard blow at unionism if it were not for the fact that an 
 employer will not usually combat in the courts peaceful 
 picketing unless it is used in conjunction with an unlawful 
 strike or boycott. As a practical matter it may then be said 
 that peaceful picketing as an adjunct of any other lawful 
 activity of a union is not likely to lead to any action at law. 
 If used in its really civilized form this most powerful 
 weapon of struggling unionism may be still of avail in in- 
 dustrial disputes. 
 
 Thus far we have been considering the union mainly as 
 a body of workingmen ; it has another aspect, that of a 
 body of consumers ; and it is upon this quality of its mem- 
 bership that the union relies in the activity usually known 
 by the name of the boycott. In its conflict with the em- 
 ployer the boycott is a frequent weapon of the union. In 
 itself, as will be seen, it is not a very efficient weapon ; but 
 in conjunction with the strike, with which indeed it is gen- 
 erally used, it often enables the union to achieve what an 
 unaided strike might not have attained. There are two de- 
 grees of the boycott, primary and secondary ; but the courts 
 do not seem to observe the distinction, some including the 
 two classes under one head, others limiting the two classes 
 at entirely different points, and a great number having ref- 
 erence to the second class alone when they speak of the boy- 
 cott. The primary boycott is the act of a combination of 
 individuals who agree among themselves not to patronize a 
 certain dealer. The secondary boycott is the act of a com- 
 bination which tries to economically outlaw a certain dealer 
 by intimidating third parties, either by strike or boycott, to 
 prevent them from patronizing this dealer. Assuming the 
 object of the boycott to be legal, the primary boycott is gen-
 
 30 
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [176 
 
 erally a legal activity of the union, whereas the secondary 
 boycott is quite as generally deemed illegal. 
 
 In Maryland we have a leading case on this subject, and 
 it may be well to consider it specifically. The case, My 
 Maryland Lodge v. Adt,^* is one of secondary boycott, but 
 the court laid down some additional law of utmost impor- 
 tance. Adt, upon refusing an increase in wages, had been 
 struck against. Further, the union sent circulars to the 
 brewers who were in the habit of contracting with Adt for 
 machinery asking them to boycott Adt on the ground that 
 he no longer had a union shop. Upon failure of the brew- 
 ers to meet this request, the union circulated "unfair" 
 broadsides against them; and in self defense the brewers 
 were compelled to withdraw their patronage from Adt, 
 whose business was thereby practically ruined. On these 
 facts the Court of Appeals upheld an injunction against the 
 union, and declared such methods of warfare manifestly 
 unfair and actionable. The court in this case merely held 
 illegal the secondary boycott; but some of its language is 
 so loose that it may be possible to interpret it as declaring 
 all boycotts illegal, especially as the court makes no dis- 
 tinction between the two classes of boycott. It is submit- 
 ted, however, that if the court was referring to the primary 
 boycott per se, its stand is hardly justified. 
 
 The distinction, indeed, between the two classes of boy- 
 cott has, as was intimated, been sustained by the great 
 weight of authority.'^^ An individual has a right to bestow 
 his patronage where he wishes; and the mere fact that he 
 combines with others in carrying out his purpose does not 
 make the act prima facie actionable. To make it illegal 
 there must be in the object or means of the primary boy- 
 cott some malicious purpose, as the injury of another with- 
 out any direct benefit to those engaged in the boycott. The 
 
 24 100 Md. 238; 56 Atl. 721 ; 68 L. R. A. 752 (1905). 
 
 25 See American Federation of Labor v. Buck's Stove & Range 
 Co., 33 App. D. C. 83; 32 L. R. A. (N. S.) 748; and note on this 
 case in L. R. A.
 
 177] THE LABOR UNION 3 1 
 
 primary boycott being in itself lawful, any publication in 
 furtherance thereof, if that is the purpose of the publi- 
 cation and no intimidation or coercion is intended, would 
 also be lawful ;^^ but here again, as in the question of pick- 
 eting, the courts are prone to see intimidation in any pub- 
 lication, with the result that the unions must be most care- 
 ful in their use of legally recognized weapons. If, then, it 
 is dangerous to publish unfair lists in primary boycotts, it 
 is of course an absolute infringement upon the rights of 
 another to publish such a list in pursuance of a secondary 
 boycott. 
 
 It is needless and would be indeed useless to enter here 
 into a detailed investigation of what has been held illegal 
 boycott. The rule seems to be that if a third party has 
 been drawn into the controversy between the two contend- 
 ing factions, then the boycott is a secondary boycott and 
 he against whom it is being prosecuted may recover for his 
 damages.^'' This, although it seems to be well-settled law, 
 involves an inconsistency. Take, for example, the Adt case : 
 employees strike for increase of wages and in pursuance of 
 that strike for a perfectly lawful purpose institute a boy- 
 cott against the employer. In the Adt case there was some 
 question as to the legality of the means used to enforce the 
 boycott, but that does not seem to have influenced the de- 
 cision. Then, granting the legality of the strike, why should 
 it be illegal to enlist the sympathies of third persons who 
 deal with the employer? If these third persons are injured, 
 
 26 See note in 32 L. R. A. (N. S.) 1017; and cases cited there, 
 mostly New York cases. 
 
 27 Thus it has been held that " a combination of employees to 
 compel their employers, by threats of quitting and by actually quit- 
 ting their service, to withdraw from a mutually profitable relation 
 with a third person having no effect on the character or reward of 
 the employees' services, for the purpose of injuring such third per- 
 son, is a boycott and an unlawful conspiracy." (Thomas v. Cinn. 
 etc. Ry. Co., 62 Fed. 803) ; and that it was illegal for a union to 
 boycott an employer of non-union labor by refusing to work for 
 another employer who furnished him with supplies. [Burnham v. 
 Dowd, 104 N. E. 841 (Mass.).] There are innumerable cases on 
 this subject, generally decided on a question of fact.
 
 32 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [178 
 
 are coerced into the boycott, they have their redress in the 
 courts against the union. But why should the employer be 
 entitled to plead in a controversy between himself and the 
 union the injury of these third parties, who themselves do 
 not complain? The employer, it is true, is injured, but he 
 is injured in the course of fair competition between himself 
 and the union, and it is damnum absque injuria. If we 
 grant that a strike legally pursued is justified to raise wages, 
 a boycott for the same purpose, as long as no third person 
 complains, would seem equally justifiable, and the employer 
 should not be heard to voice a third party's injury in pro- 
 tection of himself. 
 
 Perhaps the real explanation of the courts' antagonism 
 to the boycott is to be found in their fear of its potentiali- 
 ties — for it is one of the most efficient weapons of the union. 
 But if this explanation is true, the courts are certainly 
 guilty of a wrongful invasion of the legislative dom.ain and 
 the explanation is merely a confession of this. 
 
 Closely connected with the boycott and apparently a much 
 more effective means of enforcing the boycott is the fre- 
 quently occurring rule of a labor union forbidding its mem- 
 bers to handle non-union material, that is, material pre- 
 pared by non-union men. It has been held that the union 
 may under conditions issue such a rule. Where the object 
 of a labor union or the purpose of its action under this rule 
 is principally to injure another or his property, the agree- 
 ment forming the union is unlawful ; but where the pur- 
 pose is only to advance the interests of the members 6f the 
 union the union is not illegal and such rules may legally 
 be enforced. ^^ Here, again, the distinction crops up be- 
 tween the " mutual advantage " of the laborers and the 
 malicious injury of another. "So long as the motive [of 
 the rule] is not malicious, the object not unlawful nor op- 
 pressive, and the means neither deceitful nor fraudulent, 
 
 28 Bossert v. Brotherhood of Carpenters and Joiners of America, 
 137 N. Y. 321; Gill Engraving Co. v. Doerr, 214 Fed. iii.
 
 179] "^^^ LABOR UNION 33 
 
 the result is not a [illegal] conspiracy, although it may 
 necessarily work injury to other persons, "^° 
 
 The distinction between this rule and the boycott is not 
 easy to perceive at first blush. The courts have distin- 
 guished it upon the ground that the rule was laid down 
 before any difference arose between the employer and the 
 union, and that hence it might impliedly have entered into 
 the service contract. Moreover, as stated above, the courts 
 have recognized the direct interests of the laborers in the 
 rule ; and, finally, the quarrels have been directly between 
 the employer and the union, the boycotted dealer did not 
 enter into the consideration. This method of boycotting is 
 naturally only applicable in well-organized trades with a 
 stable membership, and the older and more stable unions 
 have to a great extent made use of it. It would seem one 
 of the most effective instruments that the unions can use ; 
 for, not being tainted with the ancient obloquy of trade 
 unions, the courts have been more liberal in their attitude 
 toward it. 
 
 Precisely corresponding to the boycott, but issuing from 
 the other party to the controversy, is the blackhst. It is a 
 weapon that employers have been fond of using against the 
 strike. As such it would seem to have generally been held 
 legal. That is, if the employer of the shop which is the 
 object of the strike should distribute to his brother employ- 
 ers, who are associated with him in trade agreements, a 
 list of his striking employees with the intention that these 
 other employers should refuse the strikers employment in 
 their shops, the courts would almost certainly hold such a 
 blacklist lawful. But it is practically impossible to be abso- 
 lutely certain how far the courts will go in holding any 
 blacklist lawful. They are here confronted with the same 
 conflict that has been evident in all the law of union activi- 
 ties, the conflict of the right of the employers to carry on 
 their business as they see fit and the right of the employees 
 
 29 National FireproofinR Co, v. Mason Builders' Ass'n. 169 Fed. 
 256, 26 L. R. A, (N. S.) 148,
 
 34 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l8o 
 
 to the free use of their laboring powers. As was said in a 
 recent Maryland case, "neither [the employer nor em- 
 ployee] has the right to interfere, without cause, with the 
 business or occupation of the other."^° And the courts, it 
 would seem, are more opposed to the combination mani- 
 festing itself in the blacklist than they are to the combina- 
 tions of laborers against laborer. We have seen in our con- 
 sideration of strikes directed against the non-union work- 
 ingman, how eager the courts are to protect the laborer 
 against the combination, but they have been somewhat re- 
 strained by the fact that the two competitors are in the same 
 economic position. The blacklist, however, represents a 
 combination of economically strong employers functioning 
 to deprive a workman of his only means of livelihood. It 
 is natural that the courts should be more prone to condemn 
 the blacklist than a combination of workingmen. 
 
 The blacklist, nevertheless, does not always offend the 
 courts. As a counter-weapon to the strike, as has been 
 said, the blacklist is a proper thing. On the other hand, if 
 the list circulated among the employers is tinged with slan- 
 der, the workingman has naturally a clear right of action 
 against the employers. In between these two extremes, it 
 is often difficult to classify a blacklist. " Any malicious in- 
 terference with the business or occupation," as our Court 
 of Appeals has said, " if followed by damage, is an action- 
 able wrong."^^ This is a safe enough guide where actual 
 malice, or malice in fact, is evident in the case, as it was 
 in our Maryland case ; but the concept of malice in law, 
 though often used by the courts in their reasoning in black- 
 listing cases, is no longer of much practical use because of 
 its extreme elasticity. It would, perhaps, be sufficiently 
 correct to say that when a blacklist is used against striking 
 employees or to gain a legitimate interest of the employ- 
 ers, it is legal, but when it is used merely as a disciplinary 
 
 30 Willner v. Silverman, 109 Md. 341 ; 71 Atl. 063 ; 24 L. R. A. 
 (N. S.) 895 (1910). 
 
 31 Ibid.
 
 l8l] THE LABOR UNION 35 
 
 measure against an employee and to attain no advantage 
 for the employer, it is an actionable tort against the indi- 
 vidual workingman. That, at least, is the Maryland law. 
 
 This careful regard of the courts for the welfare of the 
 individual is not directed strictly towards the unions, and 
 is, therefore, perhaps not appropriate in this place ; but so 
 intimately is the blacklist related as a counter measure to 
 the strike and boycott that the unions have really been 
 much strengthened by this judicial curtailment of the em- 
 ployer's powers. It seems, in most cases, that the decrees 
 of the courts have been adequate enough for the protection 
 of the laborers, but the public has not been — or, perhaps, 
 it is more correct to say, the unions have not been — suf- 
 ficiently satisfied with this judicial protection; and in many 
 states laws have been passed prohibiting employers from 
 circulating blacklists. Innocent information is not prohib- 
 ited, so that these statutes have uniformly been held con- 
 stitutional. Maryland has no such statute, but from the 
 tendencies of the court in the case of Willner v. Silver- 
 man^^ such a statute if it could be made effective would 
 seem desirable, especially from the union standpoint. 
 
 At the possible risk of digression, I want to call attention 
 here to perhaps the greatest encouragement that has yet 
 been extended to unionism by legal enactment. With no 
 special reference at present to Maryland law, it is yet in- 
 dicative of a tendency in the law which may at some future 
 time be realized. There have been several state statutes 
 and one federal statute relating to interstate commerce 
 which have declared criminally illegal the discharge or 
 threatened discharge of employees because of membership 
 in any labor organization. Practically all of these statutes 
 have been held unconstitutional as depriving the employer 
 of the right of contract without due process of law ; but in 
 the Supreme Court^^ three forcible dissenting opinions 
 
 82 Ibid. 
 
 33 Adair v. U. S., 208 U. S. 161 ; 52 L. ed. 436; and see note in this 
 edition on State cases ; Coppage v. Kansas, 236 U. S. i ; 59 L. ed. 441.
 
 36 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [182 
 
 were filed against this position, the one by Justice Holmes 
 in the earlier case in particular being most suggestive of 
 future modifications of the severity of the doctrine under- 
 lying the majority opinion. 
 
 The closed shop contract is the highest attainment of 
 trade unionism. It is still a method, a means to an end, 
 but it smacks more of the ultimate desideratum than do 
 any of the other activities of the unions. Once the closed 
 shop is attained in an industry, collective bargaining has 
 achieved its most valuable guarantee; and collective bar- 
 gaining is a primary goal of unionism. Unions, according 
 to their advocates and publicists, are striving, not for the 
 elevation of the workingman above his rightful economic 
 condition, but for the absolute equality of the laborer with 
 the capitalist and the landlord as a claimant in distribution. 
 All the phenomena of unionism which we have considered 
 are indications of this ambition — the strike and boycott, the 
 weapons of the militant, struggling union ; the agreement 
 against non-union material, a defense of the victorious 
 union; and the closed shop, the security of the old and 
 firmly established union. It is therefore obvious that the 
 law of the closed shop agreement — more often an agree- 
 ment than a formal contract — will be somewhat different 
 from that of the other methods of unionism. Yet, in study- 
 ing the agreement against non-union materials and the 
 strike against the non-union workingman, a foundation has 
 been laid down. 
 
 The law seems to be that an agreement between one em- 
 ployer and a labor union that he will employ only such 
 laborers, members of that union, as the union shall specify 
 is completely enforceable. Equally unenforceable is an 
 agreement on the same point between all the branches of 
 a labor union within a certain territory and all the em- 
 ployers of that trade within the same territory.^* Between 
 these two extremes lies the debatable ground. It is as- 
 sumed, of course, in this discussion that the benefit of the 
 
 3* McCord V. Thompson-Starrett Co., 198 N. Y. 587 ; 92 N. E. 1090.
 
 183] THE LABOR UNION 37 
 
 agreement is material to the two parties and that there is no 
 malice. The law as to this has been sufficiently threshed 
 out.^^ The law, then, with respect to the closed shop agree- 
 ment is precisely that of the common law of contracts in 
 restraint of trade, that of conspiracies in unreasonable or 
 indirect restraint of trade. Where the agreement between 
 the employer and the union is too monopolistic within too 
 comprehensive a territory — of course much smaller than the 
 unreasonable district in trade monopolies — the agreement is 
 an unreasonable restraint upon the individual's freedom of 
 contract and the competition of the non-union laborer is 
 too completely stifled. This is the opinion of the courts. In 
 the eyes of the economist — and the argument seems sound 
 — a trade union with complete monopoly of the labor in its 
 district is the acme of perfection of competition, of com- 
 petition among the elements of production. 
 
 The courts seem to have been led into this distinction as 
 to extent of monopoly in a rather haphazard manner, if 
 not absolutely against their will. The law of the closed 
 shop has been most fully developed in New York. In the 
 earliest case^^ the court held invalid a contract between a 
 brewers' association and a labor union providing that no 
 employee of the association should be allowed to work for 
 longer than a specified time without becoming a member 
 of the union. In the second case,^^ after several appeals 
 and reversals, the court held valid a contract between an 
 employer and a labor union providing for an absolutely 
 closed shop. In this case the court specifically stated that 
 the early case was not overruled. The critics immediately 
 emphasized the conflict. The only way of resolving the 
 conflict was to develop the distinction between the single 
 employer in the enforceable agreement and the association 
 
 3s Cases concerning the closed shop in which this point is devel- 
 oped are: Berry v. Donovan, 188 Mass. 353; 5 L. R. A. (N. S.) 899; 
 Kissan v. U. S. Printing Co. of Ohio, 199 N. Y. 76; 92 N. E. 214; 
 Hoban v. Dempsey, 104 N. E. 717 (Mass.). 
 
 3« Curran v. Galen, 152 N. Y. 33; 37 L. R. A. 802 (1897). 
 
 "Jacobs V. Cohen, 183 N. Y. 207; 2 L. R. A. (N. S.) 292 (1905).
 
 38 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [184 
 
 in the unenforceable. This distinction was developed in 
 subsequent cases, and has been accepted as the rule in cases 
 in other states.^^ Naturally, what is lawful in this respect 
 for the labor unions is lawful for the employers, and there 
 are several cases in which open shop agreements between 
 employers aimed directly at the unions have been held 
 legal.^® 
 
 It might be profitable to present a brief and concise 
 resume and to draw some conclusions from the Maryland 
 law of labor combinations before proceeding to the specific 
 statutes which are based upon or closely allied to the exist- 
 ence of labor unions. Since the statute of 1884 labor or- 
 ganizations are not per se conspiracies. An act which is 
 lawful for an individual is therefore perfectly lawful for 
 a union to undertake, with the one possible exception, most 
 apparent in the law of picketing, that in certain circum- 
 stances numbers themselves may be a menace to the peace 
 of society. However, there is growing up in the law of 
 torts a theory which is finding great application in labor 
 cases that an act, though conducted for perfectly legitimate 
 ultimate ends and in a perfectly lawful manner, may yet be 
 actionable if immediately inspired by an improper motive. 
 Thus a strike lawfully conducted to strengthen the union 
 may still constitute a tort against a non-union man if its 
 motive is to secure his discharge. On this proposition of 
 law is based the rule that the activities of labor organiza- 
 tions must have the direct purpose of improving the wel- 
 fare of the members of the association, and may only inci- 
 dentally, indirectly and perhaps unsubstantially affect a 
 third uninterested party. 
 
 But these generalities do not help us much to appreciate 
 the trend of the Maryland decisions. The law of the union 
 is in its present state of uncertainty because of conflict of 
 
 »8 Connors v. Connoly, 86 Conn. 641, 45 L. R. A. 564; and note in 
 L. R. A. 
 
 39 Hitchman Coal & Coke Co. v. Mitchell, 172 Fed. 963 ; Goldfield 
 Consol. Mines Co. v. Goldfield Miners' Union, 159 Fed. 500.
 
 1 85] THE LABOR UNION 39 
 
 two generalities : " improving the welfare of the members " 
 and the indirectness with which the interest of a third party 
 is affected. The courts until very recently have been in- 
 clined by their training, by their leaning in the direction of 
 the individualistic philosophy of freedom, towards protect- 
 ing the rights of the third party, no matter how incidentally 
 they may be infringed upon. It is fair to say that they did 
 not truly understand the significance of unionism, the at- 
 tempt to secure economic equality by strengthening the bar- 
 gaining power of the laborers. Maryland law, of which the 
 last case was decided in 1909, is still in this stage. In the 
 Lucke case the court recognized no rights of the union to 
 secure employment for its own members, but considered 
 merely the technical right of the individual. In the Adt 
 case the court might have justified its decision on certain 
 forcible methods of the union, but it contents itself with 
 unconditionally outlawing the boycott no matter what the 
 actual economic conditions may be. Precedent is still su- 
 preme. In the Willner case, the last word on the subject, 
 the court might possibly be said to have taken subconscious 
 cognizance of economic forces, but in reality the decision 
 in favor of the unions was reached by purely individualis- 
 tic reasoning. It may be hoped in view of certain tendencies 
 manifesting themselves in other lines of decisions that the 
 Court of Appeals will in its next union case take a broader 
 view of the province of law, but as the decisions now stand, 
 though the results in all these cases are perhaps justifiable, 
 the law is not in a satisfactory condition and Maryland does 
 not deserve a position with the more advanced states. 
 
 Statutes Relating to Unionism. — The union label is now 
 recognized as one of the useful, if not necessary, instru- 
 ments of organized labor. The law on the subject is rather 
 difficult and the decisions most conflicting; but the Mary- 
 land legislature of 1892 has relieved us of the necessity of 
 anything more than a cursory sketch of the unwritten law. 
 In the earliest cases the union label was defended by its 
 advocates as a trade-mark. The majority of decisions, how-
 
 40 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l86 
 
 ever, held that inasmuch as the union is not the owner, 
 manufacturer or seller of goods to which the label is at- 
 tached, the label is not a valid trade-mark nor entitled to 
 protection or registration as such.*° Rebuffed by the com- 
 mon law courts, the unions strove in equity proceedings to 
 enjoin the counterfeiting and unauthorized use of the label. 
 Here they were more successful, the courts viewing the 
 label as union property. The courts declared that the con- 
 cept of property should not be fixed, but progressive, de- 
 veloping with the growing society. Surely, therefore, the 
 label is property. Witness the reasoning in a Maryland 
 case in a lower court: 
 
 "The object and effect of this label, as used by plaintiffs 
 on their associates, is to increase the value of their labor. 
 ... It will not be denied that every freeman has a prop- 
 erty right in his own labor. . . . From this broad principle 
 it is easy to develop the particular proposition, that an asso- 
 ciation of men who combine for the purpose of increasing, 
 by legitimate means, the general demand for their common 
 labor, have a property right in whatever lawful instrumen- 
 tality they can succeed in creating and controlling for that 
 purpose. 
 
 "If the combination for that purpose be legitimate, and 
 the label itself as used be a lawful instrumentality and con- 
 tains no fraudulent misrepresentation, the label is entitled 
 to the recognition of a court of equity as a property right, 
 and any fraudulent imitation of it will be suppressed."*^ 
 The reasoning here employed is valid and convincing, but 
 nevertheless this opinion is in conflict with most courts of 
 the country which have refused to view the label as prop- 
 erty in the absence of statute. 
 
 , Not satisfied with this tendency in the Maryland law — 
 for, of course, it was not authority since the case did not 
 reach the Court of Appeals — the unions caused the enact- 
 
 *o See Martin, Law of Labor Union, pp. 423-429, for a more de- 
 tailed discussion with references. 
 
 <i Cigar Makers' Union of Balfo. v. Link. Baltimore Circuit 
 Court, 1886; reported in 29 L. R. A. 202, note.
 
 187] THE LABOR UNION 4 1 
 
 ment of the law referred to above, legalizing and protect- 
 ing union labels.*^ The first section declares that " when- 
 ever any . . . union of workingmen have adopted, or shall 
 hereafter adopt for their protection any label . . . announc- 
 ing that goods to which such label . . . shall be attached, 
 .were manufactured by a member or members of such union, 
 it shall not be lawful for any person or corporation to coun- 
 terfeit or imitate such label ;" and following sections de- 
 clare such counterfeiting a criminal proceeding, enjoinable 
 by courts of equity, and cause for damages. Registration 
 of the label is also provided for. No case seems to have 
 arisen under this statute ; but in other states similar statutes 
 have been attacked as class legislation, but without excep- 
 tion they have been upheld.*^ 
 
 There is, moreover, on the statute books a law which was 
 passed in the interests of, if not as a direct political plum 
 .for, the labor unions which is absolutely and undeniably 
 unconstitutional. It is the law^* which directs the "public 
 printer " to affix to all public printing the label of the Inter- 
 national Typographical Union. Precisely similar ordinances 
 and acts have been held unconstitutional in many Western 
 States as in clear violation of the guarantee by the Four- 
 teenth Amendment to the federal Constitution of the secur- 
 ity of property under the due process of law clause.*^ 
 , The final problem which the state has to solve with ref- 
 erence to unionism may under certain conditions become 
 the most important of all. It is the reconciliation of the 
 two quarrelling factions in any labor dispute or the pre- 
 .vention of the dispute itself. There are two main classes 
 into which legislation of this sort falls, arbitration and con- 
 ciliation, and each of these is again sub-divided into com- 
 pulsory and voluntary methods. 
 , In arbitration both sides, labor and capital, appear before 
 
 *2 Acts 1892, Ch. 357 ; Code 1912, Art. 27, Sees. 50-55. 
 ■*3 See note in 39 L. R. A. (N. S.) 1190. 
 ** Code 1911, Art. 78, Sec. 9. 
 
 *5 See Miller v. Des Moines, 23 L. R. A. (N. S.) 815 (Iowa), and 
 note.
 
 42 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [l88 
 
 an arbitral board, usually, though not always, composed of 
 a representative of each contestant and a non-partisan chair- 
 man, and present their case. The board deliberates and 
 hands down a binding decision. If reference to an arbitral 
 board is compelled by the State, the arbitration is compul- 
 sory ; if reference to the board is dependent upon the agree- 
 ment of the parties to the dispute, the arbitration is volun- 
 tary. Purely voluntary arbitration is rarely found in present 
 day statute books, for it has been found that state activity 
 is entirely unprofitable in this method of industrial peace. 
 Compulsory arbitration has been tried in Australia with 
 varying results in the different states. It suffers from the 
 fact that there is no settled theory of wages discovered as 
 yet upon which the board can render its decision, which 
 must accordingly be a compromise, a result not too favor- 
 able to the principle of collective bargaining. Compulsory 
 arbitration would possibly be unconstitutional in the United 
 States.*" 
 
 Midway between arbitration and conciliation as a means 
 of industrial peace is a hybrid form of endeavoring to force 
 peace by an impartial investigation of the dispute and a 
 full publication of the results of the investigation, both 
 facts and conclusions. By providing publicity, this method 
 seeks to inform public opinion of the true state of affairs, 
 and by directing it against one contestant, to compel this 
 contestant to yield in the controversy. This method usually 
 occurs in legislation in company with voluntary arbitration 
 or conciliation and smacks a little of each of these. It dif- 
 fers from the compulsory methods in that it relies upon 
 the force of public opinion rather than on the physical sanc- 
 tion of the State. Properly administered it should be 
 effective. 
 
 Compulsory conciliation, or perhaps more correctly com- 
 pulsory investigation, is a logical development of the 
 method of publicity. It seeks to prevent industrial unrest 
 
 ^ <8 See, however, Wilson v. New (decided March 17, 1917) as lend- 
 ing some credence to the contrary view.
 
 189] THE LABOR UNION 43 
 
 rather than to reconcile two contending parties. As suc- 
 cessfully employed in Canada, workmen and employers 
 before declaring a strike or lock-out must appear before a 
 conciliation board and state their case in full. This board 
 then gives its decision and award which, however, is not 
 binding upon either party: the strike or lock-out may be 
 consummated as though there were no decision. The find- 
 ings of the board have, however, been meanwhile pub- 
 lished, and public opinion is relied upon to prevent the 
 party to whom the decision was adverse from carrying out 
 its intent to strike or lock out. This scheme seems the one 
 most suited to an American State and its success in Canada 
 testifies to its worth. 
 
 The Maryland laws belong to the class of voluntary arbi- 
 tration laws and one of them has the added provision for 
 an impartial investigation. The first law,*^ passed in 1878, 
 although it does not explicitly refer to strikes, provides that 
 '' whenever any controversy shall arise between any corpor- 
 ation incorporated by this State in which the State may be 
 interested as a stockholder or creditor, and any person in 
 the employment of such corporation, which, in the opinion 
 of the board of public works, shall tend to impair the use- 
 fulness or prosperity of such corporation, the board of pub- 
 lic works . . . shall have the riglit to propose to the parties 
 to said controversy that the same shall be settled by arbi- 
 tration " ; and, upon the consent of the parties to the arbi- 
 tration, the board is given the power to make a conclusive 
 award. This law is only of antiquarian interest and, as far 
 as I have been able to ascertain, has never been made use 
 of in a labor dispute. It is of the most inadequate type of 
 this kind of legislation. 
 
 The present law was first enacted in 1904, but was radi- 
 cally amended by an addition in 1916.*^ The early law 
 gave to the then Chief of the Bureau of Statistics and In- 
 
 *'' Laws 1878, Ch. 379; Code 1912, Art. 7. 
 
 "Laws 1904, Ch. 671; Code 1911, Art. 89, Sees. 3-11, as amended 
 by Laws 1916, Ch. 406.
 
 44 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [19O 
 
 formation power to mediate, arbitrate or investigate. 
 Thoug'h still on the books, the provisions of this law have 
 been repeated in a form so much more efficient in the 1916 
 amendment that the early law should be practically super- 
 seded. No description of this amendment could be more 
 clear or concise than the text itself. 
 
 " It shall be the duty of the State Board of Labor and 
 Statistics to do all in its power to promote the voluntary 
 arbitration, mediation and conciliation of controversies and 
 disputes between employers and employes, and to avoid re- 
 sort to lockouts, boycotts, blacklists, discriminations and 
 legal proceedings in or arising out of such controversies and 
 disputes and matters of employment. In pursuance of this 
 duty, the said board may, whenever it deems advisable, but 
 subject to the approval of the Governor, appoint boards of 
 arbitration for the consideration and settlement of such con- 
 troversies and disputes, and may provide for the necessary 
 expenses of such arbitration boards, and for such reason- 
 able compensation to the members serving thereon as the 
 said board may deem proper, not exceeding, however, the 
 sum of five dollars per day for each member for each day 
 during which such member is engaged in work upon said 
 arbitration boards. The said board shall prescribe rules of 
 procedure for such arbitration boards, and the said arbitra- 
 tion boards shall have the power to cotiduct investigations 
 and hold hearings, to summon witnesses, and enforce their 
 attendance through the ordinary processes of law in the 
 cities and counties in which such arbitration boards may 
 meet, subject to all the penalties for non-attendance to 
 which witnesses in ordinary civil cases are subject, and in 
 like manner may require the production of books, docu- 
 ments and papers and may administer oaths, all to the same 
 extent that such powers are possessed and exercised by the 
 civil courts of the State; and said arbitration boards shall 
 make, report and publish findings for the settlement of such 
 controversies and disputes. The said Board of Labor and 
 Statistics shall itself have like power to conduct investiga-
 
 ipi] THE LABOR UNION 45 
 
 tions and hold hearings, summon and enforce the attend- 
 ance of witnesses, administer oaths, require the production 
 of books, documents and papers, and make and pubhsh re- 
 ports and findings with respect to any and all matters cov- 
 ered by this section. Subject to the approval of the Gover- 
 nor, the board may appoint and designate a deputy, and fix 
 his compensation, who shall be known as the chief mediator, 
 and who, together with any assistants who may be assigned 
 by the board, shall have in charge the execution of the pro- 
 visions of this section, under the direction and supervision 
 of the board. The chief mediator may act upon any board 
 of arbitration, but in such event he shall receive no com- 
 pensation therefor in addition to his ordinary salary." This 
 law, providing as it does for arbitration, and if that fails 
 for investigation and publication with very efficient means 
 of administration, is about as good a law as could be hoped 
 for. It might be argued, and the author does believe, that 
 compulsory conciliation would be a more effective means of 
 industrial peace, but the law as it stands is adequate. If it 
 fails in its purpose, it will be because of the inevitable weak- 
 ness of a law depending on public opinion for its sanction 
 or because of a slackness in its administration.
 
 CHAPTER III 
 The Workmen's Compensation Law 
 
 History. — The Workmen's Compensation Law occupies a 
 peculiar place in the study of the labor law. It differs from 
 the law considered in the last chapter in that it is the result 
 of a definite policy of state activity and is not a growth of 
 the common law. It differs from the statute law, which 
 will be the subject of the following chapters, in that it is 
 not an addition to, but an amendment of the common law. 
 It is the only instance we have in the field of Maryland 
 labor law of a deliberate wholesale repeal of a whole sec- 
 tion of common law principles which were conceived to be 
 antiquated and unsuited to modern industrial conditions, 
 and the substitution for them of a new statutory system of 
 law. 
 
 Maryland's experience with workmen's compensation 
 laws has been peculiar and somewhat disconcerting. It was 
 the first State in America to adopt this now almost univer- 
 sal social legislation, but it was decidedly not in the van in 
 adopting a really satisfactory law, if indeed the present 
 law is entirely satisfactory. Its priority in the field is per- 
 haps explained by the horribly inequitable degree to which 
 its law of master and servant, especially the harsh doctrines 
 of assumption of risk and fellow-servant negligence, had 
 developed. 
 
 The first act of 1902,^ " conceived in ignorance and quickly 
 forgotten," was an act to create a Cooperative Insurance 
 Fund. The law was limited in scope, applying only to 
 "coal or clay mining, quarrying, steam or street railroads 
 . . . and any incorporated town, city or coimty engaged in 
 the work of constructing any sewer, excavation or other 
 
 1 Laws 1902, Ch. 139, 
 
 46
 
 193] "^^^ workmen's compensation law 47 
 
 physical structure, or the contractors of any such town,'* 
 etc., an estimated coverage of about ten thousand employ- 
 ees.^ The act was what may be called a pseudo-elective 
 compensation scheme, which will be treated at greater 
 length in the following section. It provided that the em- 
 ployers covered should be liable for " death or injury caused 
 by the negligence of the employer or by that of any servant 
 or employee of such employer " unless they contributed to 
 the insurance fund which was provided for by the statute. 
 Half of these contributions, the amounts of which were set 
 forth in the act, might be deducted from the wages of the 
 employees. The only insurance provided was a benefit of 
 one thousand dollars for the death of every employee oc- 
 curring " in the course of employment and by causes aris- 
 ing therein." No provision was made for compensation for 
 permanent or temporary injury, and in this respect the 
 workman seemed worse off than before the passage of the 
 law. The only principle of compensation which seems to 
 have been accepted in full was the liability of the employer 
 for the faults of his employees. The law was of question- 
 able value as a piece of social legislation ; its real value was 
 as an opening wedge for future enactments. 
 
 This act remained in force for nearly two years, during 
 which time it seems to have been well administered, though 
 only five death benefits were paid out of it. The fund was 
 protected from insolvency by the mutual insurance feature 
 which was borrowed from Germany — practically the only 
 sound feature which was obtained from the extensive ex- 
 perience of European countries. In 1904, however, in a 
 case in the Court of Common Pleas of Baltimore City' — 
 the act never came before the Court of Appeals — the law 
 was held unconstitutional, not as abrogating the constitu- 
 tional rights of the employer, as we would generally expect 
 to-day, but as denying to the employee a jury trial when he 
 
 2 See G. E. Barnett in 16 Quarterly Journal of Economics, p. 591. 
 
 3 Franklin v. United Railways and Electric Co., reported in the 
 Daily Record for April 29, 1904.
 
 48 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [194 
 
 wished to recover for the negligence of the employer. " The 
 act," said the court, "embraces cases where the death had 
 been caused by the negligence of the employer, cases where 
 there would have been clear right of action in the courts 
 imder existing law. It enacted that employers who had 
 made the payments provided in the act should by such pay- 
 ments be exempted from further liability. The effect was 
 ... to take away from citizens a legal right which they 
 had theretofore enjoyed, and which could be enforced by 
 them in the courts, and also to deny them a right to have 
 their cases heard before a jury." The court seems plainly 
 in error in the first part of its decision, for it was decided 
 as early as the case of Munn v. Illinois* that " a person has 
 no property, no vested interest, in any rule of common law. 
 . . . Indeed, the great office of statutes is to remedy defects 
 in the common law as they are developed, and to adapt it 
 to the changes of time and circumstances." As to the mat- 
 ter of a jury trial the question is more complex and diffi- 
 cult. Suffice it to say that jury trial is not abrogated if 
 the act is a just exercise of the police power; and, more- 
 over, most courts in the case of pseudo-elective acts have 
 refused to take cognizance of the implied coercion in these 
 acts and have decided that where those affected have con- 
 sented to be governed by the law there is no deprivation 
 of due process. That is to say that where parties have con- 
 sented to try their case without the intervention of the jury, 
 even though there is insidious, hidden coercion pressing 
 upon them, there is no infringement of their right to a jury 
 trial. Such argument is of little value and is perhaps con- 
 trary to Maryland precedent, but the courts, in spite of 
 criticism,^ have often used this species of reasoning. 
 , In 1910 the void created by this decision was filled with 
 a new cooperative relief fund,^ but even further limited 
 
 *94U. S. 1 13-134. 
 
 6 See Freund, Constitutional Status of Workmen's Compensation, 
 m 2 American Labor Legislation Review, 43 (1912). In the present 
 (1917) Maryland law the servant has reserved to him the right of a 
 civil" suit when the employer is negligent. 
 
 « Laws 1910, Ch. 153, as amended by Laws 1912, Ch. 445.
 
 195] THE workmen's compensation law 49 
 
 this time to clay and coal mining in Alleghany and Garrett 
 counties. The act provided a compulsory, cooperative in- 
 surance scheme ; but the constitutional difficulty caused by 
 the earlier decision was obviated by allowing the employee 
 to sue in the courts provided he renounced all and had 
 accepted no benefits from the Relief Fund. Another con- 
 stitutional question was avoided by calling the contributions 
 of the employers and employees "taxes," thereby resting 
 the compulsory power exercised by the State upon its tax- 
 ing rather than upon its police power. The advisability of 
 the change may, however, be considered doubtful — a leap- 
 ing from the frying pan into the fire, for here the constitu- 
 tional provision against levying a tax for a private purpose 
 stands rather obtrusively in the way, but it may be said here 
 that such a tax has been upheld in a Western court as ana- 
 logous to a license tax.'' 
 
 This act, in spite of the constitutional change of face, 
 was quite an improvement over the former law from a 
 social viewpoint. It provided, as intimated, for a fund 
 equally contributed by employer and employee — though for 
 administrative purposes the employer paid the whole tax — 
 which was put into the hands of the county commissioners 
 of the two counties to administer. The insurance for " in- 
 juries sustained in the discharge of duty" and for death 
 are far from sufficient, but there is a great increase over 
 that provided in the original act. $1500 is granted to de- 
 pendents upon the death of the wage earner ; total disability 
 entitles the injured to $750 plus one dollar a day, excluding 
 Sunday, for twenty-six weeks, about $180 additional ; par- 
 tial disability entitles him to $375 with the same addition ; 
 and temporary disability to the dollar a day benefit for 
 twenty-six weeks. The waiting time in all cases is one 
 week. Although the law provides for the payment of all 
 benefits in lump sums, the legislators recognized the possi- 
 
 ■^See State ex rel. Davis-Smith Co. v. Clausen (Wash.), 117 Pac. 
 iioi. The Maryland law was upheld in analogy to this case, see 128 
 Md. 564.
 
 50 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [196 
 
 ble evil of this method and strove to mitigate it by consti- 
 tuting the county commissioners a judicial board, first, to 
 determine who were " dependents " and, second, to appoint 
 bonded personal representatives to administer the reliefs 
 granted to the beneficiaries. This law seems to have been 
 successful, and its effectiveness was only terminated by the 
 passage of the present general compensation act. 
 
 Again in 1912 there was introduced before the legislature 
 a Workmen's Compensation bill, this time general and com- 
 pulsory in character. When the bill finally emerged, how- 
 ever, it had been completely emasculated and converted into 
 a harmless, inactive elective compensation law.^ This pro- 
 vided that it should "be lawful for any employer to make 
 a contract in writing with any employee whereby the parties 
 may agree that the employee shall become insured against 
 accident occurring in the course of employment which re- 
 sults in personal injury or death, in accordance with the 
 provisions of this act; and that in consideration of this in- 
 surance the employer shall be relieved from the conse- 
 quences of acts or omissions by reason of which he would 
 without such contract become liable." Being purely elec- 
 tive, no constitutional questions could arise from the en- 
 forcement of this act. Moreover, the law has been entirely 
 inoperative and is only interesting as the direct forerunner 
 of the present law. 
 
 The act of 1912 covered all injuries "arising out of and 
 in course of employment" except where the injury "is the 
 result of the employee's intoxication, or wilful and deliber- 
 ate act or deliberate intention to produce such injury." The 
 dependents are defined to be "widow, widower, father, 
 mother, son or daughter " unless otherwise provided. Noth- 
 ing is said with regard to alien dependents. The schedule 
 of benefits, although still rather meager, is again an im- 
 provement over the 191 o Act, and is again topped by the 
 present act. It provides for a death benefit of thrice the 
 
 8 Laws 1912, Ch. 837.
 
 197] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 5 I 
 
 annual wages, but not less than one thousand dollars; in 
 case of total disability for a benefit of at least fifty per cent 
 of the wages during disability; and in case of partial dis- 
 ability for the difiference between the total disability benefit 
 and what the injured man can earn. The waiting time is 
 again one week. The administration is vested in the par- 
 ties to the contract, but the insurance commissioner has full 
 powers of investigation. In case of any dispute as to award, 
 a board of arbitration is provided for. 
 
 These three early laws were repealed by the passage of 
 the 1914 Workmen's Compensation Law,^ which embodied 
 many of the best features of the earlier laws, especially of 
 this last elective Employers' Liability Law. The new act, 
 however, is such an advance over these experiments that a 
 comparison between them is hardly profitable. It will be 
 better, therefore, carefully to examine and analyze this law 
 as a piece of social legislation in comparison with certain 
 ideals which have been formulated for compensation 
 schemes and in comparison with the various compensation 
 schemes embodied in the laws of other states. After this 
 study, it will be necessary to consider the legal aspects of 
 the act. 
 
 The Present Law as Social Legislation. — It seems hardly 
 necessary at this late date to enter upon any detailed argu- 
 ment with reference to the merits and demerits of work- 
 ingmen's compensation laws. It is, nevertheless, almost 
 impossible to begin any discussion of this legislation with- 
 out at least some short summary of the pros and cons of 
 the question. 
 
 The objections to the laws are based upon the common 
 law individualistic conceptions of responsibility. An indi- 
 vidual, it is argued, should be responsible only for his own 
 fault and negligence. By the common law the employer 
 must supply the employee with a reasonably safe place to 
 work in, reasonably safe materials and machines to work 
 
 9 Laws 1914, Ch. 800; Code 1913, Art. loi.
 
 52 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [198 
 
 with, and reasonably competent fellow-servants to help him 
 in his work. If the employer complies with his duties and 
 the employee is nevertheless injured, the loss must He where 
 it falls, for on entering an employment the employee as- 
 sumes the risks of that employment, and visualizing the 
 possibility of injury demands higher wages as a sort of in- 
 surance. When confronted with the proposition that the 
 average workingman is by nature an optimist and neglects 
 or is unable to insure himself, the individualist shrugs his 
 shoulders and conveniently washes his hands of the improvi- 
 dent laborer. He quite as conveniently waves aside the in- 
 equality in the bargaining power of the two factors, and 
 assumes that the employee is as capable of refusing unde- 
 sirable employment as the employer is of refusing employ- 
 ment to the too pessimistic employee. The common law 
 individualist, however, is stronger when he argues against 
 saddling the employer with the burden of providing com- 
 pensation for all accidents occurring to employees arising 
 out of their employment irrespective of cause. This posi- 
 tion is absolutely invulnerable unless it can be proved that 
 the employer is in a position to shift the whole cost of the 
 compensation to the trade and thence to society. 
 
 The arguments for compensation, on the other hand, 
 attack the problem most successfully from the opposite, the 
 social point of view. From this standpoint the indictment 
 of employer's liability is complete. Unfortunately, we have 
 no Maryland statistics, but it is safe to assume that her ex- 
 perience is not materially dififerent from that of other States. 
 In the first place, an enormous majority of the industrial 
 accidents under the common law system of reparation go 
 absolutely uncompensated. Out of a total of 694,212 in- 
 juries cited in the New York commissions' report, only 
 88,841 or 12.78 per cent were compensated; and even the 
 fact that this total included minor injuries, at the most fifty 
 per cent of all, does not materially vitiate the conclusion 
 drawn. Moreover, when recovered — and the delay is often 
 great and serious — the compensation is usually most inade-
 
 199] '^^^ workmen's compensation law 53 
 
 quate, if not perchance superfluously generous. " A good 
 deal to the very few and nothing or very little to most 
 seems to be the principle upon which the liability system 
 worked itself out."^** 
 
 The common law doctrines of assumption of risk, contrib- 
 utory negligence and fellow servant negligence have also 
 come in for their own special condemnation : the assump- 
 tion of risk theory on the grounds explained above ; the 
 contributory negligence theory as being inequitable in 
 thrusting upon the employee full liability for partial fault, 
 in its essence a lazy rule of expediency ; the fellow-servant 
 doctrine as being totally inadequate in this day of enormous 
 factories and multitudinous coemployees, many of them in 
 entirely separated departments. Moreover, the hostility 
 aroused under common law principles between the laborer 
 and his employer by the consequent law-suits and bicker- 
 ings is surely not conducive to economic peace and mutual 
 understanding. Finally, and this argument being expressed 
 in dollars and cents has always been most potent with the 
 layman, the cost of administration, the lawyers' fees and 
 the court costs, have annually mounted to intolerable fig- 
 ures. This was a direct burden both upon society^^ and 
 upon the injured workingman who could ill afford the in- 
 creased load. All of these defects of the liability system 
 worked a hardship upon the laborer, generally causing him 
 to lower his standard of living, if not to become an actual 
 object of charity. To prevent this, to provide compensa- 
 tion for every injury when most needed, to save lawyers' 
 fees, to promote amicable relations between the employer 
 
 1° J. M. Rubinow, Social Insurance, p. 94. This book is rich in 
 statistical matter. Another valuable piece of statistical work is con- 
 tained in the congressional report on compensation, in S. Doc, vol. 
 12, 62d Cong. 2d sess. 
 
 1^ There is some argument that the cost of administration of the 
 compensation law, the salaries of the commission and its other ex- 
 penses, will be as great as, if not greater than, the saving accom- 
 plished by the diminution of court work. This argument, even if 
 true, can weigh little; for it is not the cost of government which the 
 compensation laws are striving to effect, but the social cost of inca- 
 pacitated, degraded workingmen.
 
 54 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [200 
 
 and the employee, these are the aims of compensation. To 
 put upon the consuming public the duty of preventing pov- 
 erty instead of mitigating wretchedness. 
 
 The arguments are clearly in favor of compensation; 
 yet the inevitable lag of legislation, the opposition, entirely 
 explicable, of the capitalist class to any social legislation 
 which will affect their pocketbooks, — and all social legis- 
 lation must necessarily affect their pocketbooks in the first 
 instance, though the intention is that part, at least, of the 
 burden shall be shifted, — the technical shortcomings of the 
 average state legislature; these have kept Maryland for 
 twelve years with insufficient compensation laws on her 
 statute books. 
 
 The Maryland act of 1914, however, provided for a com- 
 pulsory system of compensation insurance in certain enu- 
 merated extra-hazardous employments.^^ The legislature 
 flatly challenged the constitutional obstacle of due process 
 of law by making the law absolutely compulsory for those 
 employments to which it applies. This system of absolute 
 compulsion is in complete accord with theoretical opinion, 
 but in almost as complete contrast to the actual perform- 
 ances of various States. Only four states out of twenty- 
 four, that is, Maryland, New York, Ohio and Washington, 
 have compulsory schemes. The others have sought to ap- 
 pease the courts with what I have denominated in this dis- 
 cussion pseudo-elective schemes. These latter laws are 
 purely elective, though often with a presumption of election 
 unless notice to the contrary be given ; but those employers 
 who fail to elect are penalized by being deprived of the de- 
 fenses of assumption of risk, fellow-servant fault and con- 
 tributory negligence, and burdened with the added disad- 
 vantage of popular disapprobation in the jury trial which 
 must take the place of compensation proceedings. The em- 
 ployee who does not elect is left in the same position as he 
 was before the passage of the act. That is to say, the law 
 
 " Sec. 32 as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 597. See also American 
 Ice Co. V. Fitzhugh, 128 Md. 382.
 
 20l] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 55 
 
 States in effect first to the employer: You are perfectly 
 free to choose whether you will come under the compensa- 
 tion scheme or remain under liability principles ; but, if you 
 do not choose the new compensation, you will be deprived 
 of your three common law defenses and the jury will hardly 
 be disposed in your favor. Then to the employee: You 
 have the same choice ; but, if you do not take up with our 
 plan, expect no favors from us. The courts see no coercion 
 in this. The end attained by this system is practically the 
 same as that reached by the compulsory system, but in a 
 clumsy manner. The pseudo-election has been a sop to the 
 courts, which have refused to see any deprivation of due 
 process to him who has chosen to be so governed. The sub- 
 terfuge has been successful, but the courts have opened 
 themselves, and rightly, to the charge of inconsistency, a 
 quality which, interesting as it may be in other fields, is 
 deadly to the law.^^ 
 
 The Maryland law, as has been said, enumerates the 
 extra-hazardous employments which are covered, making 
 provision, however, in a blanket clause for all hazardous em- 
 ployments not specifically enumerated. The presumption, 
 therefore, is that any dangerous occupation is covered by 
 the act. On the other hand, " farm laborers, domestic ser- 
 vants, country blacksmiths, wheelwrights and similar rural 
 employments, casual employees, and any employee whose 
 salary exceeds $2000 per annum " are specifically ex- 
 cluded.^* Practically the same exclusion exists in all 
 States, sometimes by explicit exclusion as in Maryland, as 
 often by limiting the application of the compensation scheme 
 to those establishments employing more than four or five 
 workmen. This exclusion is usually justified upon the 
 grounds of administrative expediency, but it is also true 
 that the conditions in these employments are still practically 
 the same as they were before the Industrial Revolution and 
 therefore do not so forcibly demand an amendment of the 
 
 1* Freund, 2 American Labor Legislation Review, 43. 
 1* Sec. 63. 
 
 *.♦•
 
 56 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [202 
 
 law of that period. In addition to the enumerated list of 
 employments, the Maryland law provides a joint elective 
 system of compensation for all other employments in the 
 State." That this provision will be often elected seems 
 doubtful. 
 
 The provisions for compensation^^ in the Maryland law 
 cannot be rated as high as can the general scheme. The 
 increased cost of casualty insurance to the employer has 
 been such a deterrent upon the legislators that they have 
 failed rather completely to enact wisely and sufficiently. 
 The sudden increase of burden upon the employer which 
 must necessarily accompany compensation has indeed been 
 the real obstacle in the path of these laws ; yet, if we cor- 
 rectly understand the theory of compensation, this increased 
 cost is no real objection. 
 
 It has been long ascertained that one of the foremost 
 causes of poverty is the death or disability of the wage 
 earner of the family. Poverty was not originally looked 
 upon as a social disease and the natural remedies for it were 
 individualistic in character. The supremely moral and 
 provident device of " setting aside for the rainy day " was 
 the panacea for all poverty. It proved hardly a feasible 
 social cure for families stricken by an industrial accident. 
 The average workingman is naturally optimistic and rarely 
 visualizes the risk of his employment. Cooperative socie- 
 ties, furnishing social inducements as well as fraternalistic 
 benefits, were devised by the master minds to cure to some 
 extent this insidious evil. By distributing the risk, these 
 societies offered a degree of security at a low rate. The 
 remedy, however, was not complete; for these societies, 
 which developed into gilds and finally into the modern labor 
 union, naturally did not include the entire working popula- 
 tion. The outsiders still possess, of course, the old resource 
 of self -insurance, "putting aside for the rainy day," as well 
 as the newer idea of insurance in an organized insurance 
 
 15 Sec. 33. 
 
 i« Sec. 36, as amended by Laws 1916, Chs. 368, 597.
 
 203] '^'^'^ workmen's compensation law 57 
 
 company. The newer plan, it would seem, is no more prac- 
 ticable than the older, for the workingman is naturally in- 
 different to insurance, especially at the high rates which his 
 accident risk would generally bear. This antipathy, or at 
 least apathy, toward insurance is overcome in the case of 
 the labor union by the added fraternalistic advantages and 
 by the attraction furnished by the increased utility of the 
 union as a fighting machine, advantages which seem from 
 the viewpoint of insurance of rather doubtful value because 
 of the decrease in the security of the insurance funds. But, 
 accepting cooperative insurance at its greatest value, society 
 still has on its hands those poverty stricken families whose 
 uninsured wage-earners have been incapacitated or killed by 
 industrial accidents and those families, no less numerous, 
 which have suffered a serious set-back in their standard of 
 living because of insufficient insurance. Viewed, then, as 
 social legislation and totally excluding from consideration 
 the equities of the matter, compensation laws, providing 
 funds to tide over all accidents and to support the depend- 
 ents of killed workmen, are conceived to offset and to fore- 
 stall this important cause of poverty. Society is to foot the 
 bill and employers are expected to shift the burden which 
 is primarily placed upon them. It is perfectly possible to 
 argue, though it is doubtful whether the employer will en- 
 thusiastically agree with the argument, that the employer 
 should invite a large increase in insurance rates, for it has 
 often been demonstrated that the producer can be assured 
 of much greater success in shifting large increases in the 
 cost of production than small increments. 
 
 Washington is the only State in the Union, however, 
 which has interpreted the dictum of social insurance liter- 
 ally. Her compensation law provides for the care of de- 
 pendent widows and injured workmen on the same plan that 
 poor relief would be granted, though, of course, on a more 
 generous scale. Upon death, the widow is to receive twenty 
 dollars a month for life or until she marries, with five dol- 
 lars additional up to thirty-five dollars for each child under
 
 58 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2O4 
 
 sixteen. For total disability, the injured employee receives 
 twenty dollars a month if unmarried, twenty-five if mar- 
 ried, and five dollars additional up to thirty-five dollars for 
 each child under sixteen. The compensation lasts during 
 disability. In its other provisions the Washington law de- 
 parts somewhat from this principle; but, though the com- 
 pensation is somewhat low, what has been set forth suffi- 
 ciently illustrates the theory of social insurance — the pre- 
 vention and abolition of poverty — which has been developed 
 in Washington. 
 
 Most of the States, however, have met the problem by 
 providing compensation commensurate with the previous 
 earning power of the wage-earner.^^ The accidents are 
 divided into three classes, those resulting in death, in total 
 disability, and in partial disability; and a different rate of 
 compensation is provided for each. The tendency, though 
 unjustifiable on theoretical grounds, has been to divide the 
 class of partial disability into various categories and assign 
 a definite compensation to each kind of injury. The just 
 method would be to compensate the injury by a payment 
 proportionate to the loss of earning power, but the categori- 
 cal method has been made use of in order to lend certainty 
 to the amount and cost of insurance. The table on the next 
 page shows Maryland's standing as to the rate of compensa- 
 tion in comparison with other industrial States. 
 
 Maryland, it is evident, ranks low compared with these 
 other selected States. In the matter of death benefits the 
 comparison is most favorable to Maryland, but this is 
 merely because the other States are equally delinquent, not 
 because Maryland is nearer the standard. New York is 
 the only State which recognizes that the needs of a widow 
 with children are greater than those of a widow without 
 children. Maryland is prodigal towards the small family 
 of dependents and penurious toward the larger one. This 
 
 1^ Provision is made in Maryland (Sec. 47) as in some other 
 States for a consideration of the possibiUty of increase of earning 
 power when the injured workman is a youth.
 
 205] 
 
 THE WORKMEN S COMPENSATION LAW 
 
 59 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 u, 
 
 
 
 
 
 O 
 
 s 
 
 1 
 
 s 
 
 vO o^ 
 
 
 
 
 tMn 4J - • - • 
 
 •d o o o o o 
 
 MM 1 S 
 
 ' ^2 ^ 
 > T a o 
 
 vO i-J lO 
 
 O 
 to 
 
 .Q VO lO lO lO to 
 
 cd 
 
 
 , 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 ^' 
 
 
 s S 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 a 
 
 a 
 
 o 
 
 "> j_i 3 
 
 c 
 
 ^ . ci 
 
 lO . 
 
 ^0 • 4 
 
 wage 
 
 65% dif. 
 
 times annua 
 wage 
 
 .24 
 
 3j: : : : 
 
 ^^ 
 
 Y„ o o o o o 
 
 \£?vo ■* M Tj-vo 
 
 *C1 M W w M i-l 
 
 ^ 
 
 s a 
 
 J 
 
 1 1 
 
 
 J "■ 
 
 
 o o 
 
 xO O 
 
 
 
 r 
 
 1- ■* 
 
 M W 
 
 ' 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 »o 
 
 
 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO ro 
 
 
 
 .M 
 
 2 
 
 fe^-SI^ 
 
 ^2 
 
 ■kP aj : - : : 
 S^ <u - - - • 
 
 la 
 
 Mm flj O 
 
 NIM 1 
 
 
 «|M > 
 
 o 
 
 \0 ^ >o 
 
 vO tn 
 
 ■o _ _ 
 
 
 o ^ 
 
 **? „fe% 
 
 >o O O to to o 
 
 
 c^ 
 
 
 vo a 
 
 to O M t^ O 
 
 
 
 
 sop 
 
 M N w w M 
 
 * 
 
 JS4 
 
 > 
 
 o H a 
 
 ro t, 3 
 
 N|M 1 
 
 
 to 
 
 ^ij: : : ■- 
 
 OlM ^ 
 
 >£) O N to 00 00 
 
 :z; 
 
 O -3 
 
 
 o 
 
 ■^ M O 00 N 
 
 ^i 
 
 
 >o 
 
 N CO M M M 
 
 
 lO.O 
 
 
 
 
 
 *H •<-> 
 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 IT) 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 ' . (M 
 
 n 
 
 "O 
 
 CO ^ 
 
 ^ 
 
 "3 ^ o 
 
 = fc$2 ^ 
 o a*^ 
 
 J«! 
 
 a 
 
 .o ^ g 
 
 
 ^r ■' -" ' 
 O > 
 
 to o o o to o 
 to o to t- o 
 
 Hi 01 M )H M 
 
 
 
 ^^ 
 
 J^ 
 
 a<i 
 
 
 2 
 
 
 8 
 
 > 
 
 
 
 -a 
 a 
 rt 
 
 tJ5 
 
 ^^2 
 
 ^ *-=3 
 
 o o 
 
 •a ^ • 
 
 NIM • 
 
 to 
 
 
 
 lo'+j 
 
 ** 
 
 fe^ 
 
 
 
 N 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 4^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 =, c 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 4) 
 
 g 4J 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 >'S ,; 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 :-3^s 
 
 
 
 
 .aa- 
 
 •s ^- 
 
 
 
 O T3 
 
 Total disal 
 Limit of 
 Limit nf 
 
 rr> t.^ M^ 
 
 
 
 p 
 
 e2 
 
 
 
 
 1. Hand 
 
 2. Arm . 
 
 3- Foot . 
 
 4- Leg . . 
 5. Eye.. 
 
 en <n I— I 
 "bo o"^ 
 
 o 2 
 
 o^ u 
 
 TO O "^ 
 
 <n o '-' 
 
 tn P<— ^ 
 
 C -4-» 
 
 rt <u 
 u > u 
 
 6 p.«2 
 
 *^-o 
 
 
 2 ^ 
 
 .S i-i n 
 .^« w 
 
 u <U U 
 
 fcHH 
 
 00 C3 O 
 r-l i-( N
 
 6o THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [206 
 
 is clearly unjustifiable legislation. Moreover, this law 
 abruptly discontinues at the end of eight years the stipend 
 which only too often had been just sufficient to support the 
 widow or widower. This is hardly socially or economically 
 sound unless based on statistics of the average length of life 
 of a widow after the death of her husband or unless the 
 Maryland legislature wished by enactment to spur the 
 widow on to a second marriage. 
 
 The Maryland provision for total disability is entirely in- 
 adequate. An injured, incapacitated workman is, on 
 grounds of abstract justice, entitled to his whole salary dur- 
 ing incapacity. This, however, is an extreme and perhaps 
 an inexpedient position. Some reduction has to be made 
 chiefly to prevent malingering, but also to satisfy the prac- 
 tical sense of the community. In one European country, 
 however, eighty per cent of the workingman's former earn- 
 ing capacity has been granted and found expedient, but in 
 America sixty-six and two thirds per cent has been deemed 
 sufficient. Maryland provides for only fifty per cent. More 
 serious, however, is the limitation of even this compensation 
 to eight years unless the laborer by dying precludes the 
 limitation becoming an injustice. There can be no justifi- 
 cation for thus terminating the compensation. These laws 
 are framed to prevent poverty, not to postpone it for eight 
 years. 
 
 The provisions for partial disability are perhaps less 
 justifiable than those for total disability. Compensation for 
 partial disability in Maryland is divided, as intimated, into 
 two classifications : temporary partial and permanent par- 
 tial disability, and the latter is subdivided into smaller cate- 
 gories. The division is entirely useless and very confusing. 
 The compensation for temporary partial disability is fifty 
 per cent of the loss of earning power due to the injury, 
 the total compensation not to exceed $3500. If, however, 
 the same injury — and it is not impossible to conceive one — 
 should be classed as a permanent partial disability not cov- 
 ered by the special schedule, the rate of compensation is the
 
 20/] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 6 1 
 
 same as that just given, but the maximum is reduced to 
 three thousand dollars. An impasse, it seems to me. The 
 specified schedule, as will be seen from the table, seeks to 
 put a special price, based upon fifty per cent of the weekly- 
 wage, upon certain enumerated injuries. As was said 
 above, these schedules are justified merely as an insurance 
 device; as a social preventive they are unjustifiable. They 
 would admit that a man is incapacitated by the loss of a 
 member and needs compensation. However, in two or three 
 years, it is to be assumed he will have recovered and have 
 completely adjusted himself to his new mode of working, 
 being able to earn sufficient to support himself and his fam- 
 ily at a standard little below his former standard of living. 
 It is absurd. Can a machinist who has lost his hand earn 
 nearly what he has been accustomed to earn? Is a struc- 
 tural steel worker who has lost a leg a capable workman? 
 The only just compensation is a percentage of the loss of 
 earning power during the disability ; yet no American State 
 has provided unlimited compensation. Massachusetts is the 
 most exemplary, for besides providing a compensation of 
 two-thirds the loss of earning power during ten years, it 
 recognizes the fact that the injured laborer will be in greater 
 need during the first year of his injury by providing a com- 
 pensation of two-thirds his wages for this year, after which 
 the regular compensation runs. In this section more than 
 ^n any other the Maryland law is inadequate and in need 
 iof amendment. 
 
 Another feature of the law which must be considered in 
 connection with the compensation provisions of the act is 
 |;he section dealing with what is technically known as the 
 "waiting period."^^ In order to prevent malingering and 
 to exclude those innumerable minor injuries which it is in- 
 expedient to compensate, all compensation laws specify a 
 period before which no payments are granted. The stand- 
 ards adopted in this study specify from three to seven days ; 
 
 " Sees. 49 and 36 (i).
 
 62 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [208 
 
 but, though in some European countries the shorter time is 
 made use of, the prevailing practice in the United States 
 is to enforce a waiting period of fourteen days, though in 
 a few States it is only seven days. The Maryland law pro- 
 vides for a waiting period of fourteen days except in the 
 case of total disability when the workman waits only seven 
 days. During this waiting period the only outside help 
 provided for the injured employee in most acts is medical 
 and surgical aid." In Maryland the employee is entitled to 
 this aid at the expense of the employer up to the amount of 
 one hundred and fifty dollars, so that it may continue longer 
 than the waiting period if necessary.^^ 
 
 In most States the compensation provided in the sections 
 just discussed is the sole remedy of the workingman. In 
 Maryland, however, on account of the constitutional diffi- 
 culties previously set forth, whether sound or not, it is pro- 
 vided that "if the injury or death results to a workman 
 from the deliberate intention of his employer, the employee 
 or his widow . . . may have a cause of action as if this 
 Act had not been passed."^* Except in such a case the em- 
 ployee or his dependents,^^ upon proper notice to his em- 
 ployer^® and upon periodic medical examinations^'^ is en- 
 titled to his compensation and he is absolutely forbidden to 
 surrender this right by any contract.^^ 
 
 22 It is sometimes argued against the long waiting period that the 
 low paid laborer may be forced below the subsistence line in the 
 first month of his injury and never again be able to pull himself 
 above it. E. g., a laborer, with a family of four, earning twelve 
 dollars a week, is injured. His total compensation for the first 
 month of his injury will be just equal to his former weekly wage. 
 The argument is strong, but seems outweighed by considerations of 
 expediency and of penalizing improvidence. 
 
 23 Sec. 37, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 597. 
 2* Sec. 45. 
 
 25 Non-resident aliens are included. Sec. 36, as amended by Laws 
 1916, Ch. 368. 
 
 26 Sec. 38. 
 2^ Sec. 42. 
 
 28 Sec. 53. A recent decision of the Massachusetts Supreme Court 
 has stated that the compensation provided in the act does not relieve 
 the employer from liability to the parents of a minor for loss of 
 service. (King v. Viscoloid Co., 106 N. E. 988.) It seems hardly
 
 209] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 63 
 
 The compensation is paid for disability or death " result- 
 ing from an accidental personal injury . . . arising out of 
 and in the course of employment without regard to fault 
 as a cause of such injury" and "such disease or infection 
 as may naturally result therefrom." However, " where the 
 injury is occasioned by the wilful intention of the injured 
 employee to bring about the injury to himself or another, 
 or where the injury results solely from the intoxication of 
 the injured employee," no compensation is recoverable.^" 
 This or a similar section has given rise in every State to 
 an immense amount of litigation, but it will not be neces- 
 sary to delay longer here than to quote the definition 
 adopted by the Maryland commission : 
 
 "An injury is received in the course of employment 
 when it comes while the person is doing the duty which 
 he is employed to perform. It arises out of the employ- 
 ment when there is apparent to the rational mind, upon con- 
 sideration of all circumstances, a causal connection between 
 the conditions under which the work is required to be per- 
 formed and the resulting injury. Under this test if the 
 injury can be seen to have followed as a natural incident of 
 the work, and to have been contemplated by a reasonable 
 person familiar with the whole situation as a result of the 
 exposure occasioned by the nature of the employment, then 
 it arises out of employment. But it excludes an injury 
 which cannot fairly be traced to the employment as a con- 
 possible that such a decision could occur under the Maryland law. 
 The Massachusetts law is a pseudo-elective law and provides only 
 that unless the employee shall have given contrary notice, he will be 
 assumed to have surrendered his rights to any recovery outside the 
 law. This, says the court, does not abrogate the parents' right of 
 recovery for it is a " rule of statutory construction that an existing 
 common law right of action is not to be taken away by a statute 
 unless by direct enactment or necessary implication." In the Mary- 
 land act, however, it is provided that the common law rule "that 
 statutes in derogation of the common law are to be strictly construed 
 shall have no application to this act" (Sec. 61) ; and, moreover, that 
 payment under the act " shall be in lieu of any and all rights of 
 action whatsoever against any person whomsoever" (Sec. 36). 
 
 29 Sees. 14 and 63 (6), as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 593. See 
 also American Ice Co. v. Fitzhugh, 128 Md. 382.
 
 64 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2IO 
 
 tributing proximate cause and which comes from a hazard 
 to which the workman would have been equally exposed 
 apart from the employment. The causative danger must 
 be peculiar to the work and not common to the neighbor- 
 hood. It must be incidental to the character of the busi- 
 ness and not independent of the relation of master and 
 servant. It need not have been foreseen or expected, but 
 after the event it must appear to have had its origin in the 
 risk connected with the employment, and to have flowed 
 /rom that source as a rational consequence."^'' 
 
 It may be noted here that, since the compensation law 
 does not cover occupational diseases, Maryland is without 
 ^ny legal remedy for this industrial evil, for under the com- 
 fnon law doctrines it would be practically impossible to re- 
 cover from the employer in the courts. The legislative prin- 
 ciples upon which these diseases are excluded from the 
 operation of this act are perhaps sound, but some provision 
 ^hould be made in a separate act for compensation of the 
 incapacitated. It is obvious that the same reasons which 
 demanded the passage of the compensation law, the social 
 and individual effects of uncompensated injuries, as loudly 
 call for an act whereby the diseases inevitable to the occu- 
 pation should be borne by the occupation. Practically every 
 European country has a law of this kind, but the acceptance 
 ,of the principle has been slow in this country. 
 
 The provisions of the law which have been considered 
 are, of course, those most important to the laborer. It is, 
 unfortunately, this part of the Maryland law which is most 
 deficient. However, a law is not a law until it is adminis- 
 tered, and it is, therefore, of utmost importance to the bene- 
 ficiary of the act that its administration be efficient. For- 
 tunately, the sections of the Maryland act dealing with the 
 administration and insurance are most complete and most 
 satisfactory. 
 
 The greatest necessity, after once establishing the true 
 compensation principle, is to provide some method of guar- 
 
 30 Claim No. 224, quoting from McNichol v. Emp. Lia. Ass. Co., 
 215 Mass. 497.
 
 21 l] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 65 
 
 anteeing the payments to the injured employee. It is easy 
 to conceive of a compensation law totally invalidated by the 
 inability of the employers to make sufficient payments after 
 the accident because of insolvency or other unforeseen dif- 
 ^culty. Some European countries have passed laws with- 
 out any provision for the securing of the compensation, 
 leaving everything to the individual initiative of the em- 
 ployer ; but in the United States it has been unusual not to 
 pompel some kind of insurance. In Maryland, under a 
 heavy pecuniary penalty and the added disadvantage of the 
 abrogation of his three common law defenses in any suit 
 arising during the time of his non-coverage,^^ the employer 
 is compelled to secure the compensation due from him 
 either by insuring in the State Accident Fund, in an old 
 line casualty insurance company or mutual insurance asso- 
 ciation authorized to carry workmen's compensation insur- 
 ance and under the supervision of the insurance commis- 
 sioner, or by convincing the State Industrial Accident Com- 
 mission that he is strong enough financially to carry his own 
 insurance.®^ The Industrial Accident Commission has wide 
 powers of inquisition and compulsion with reference to the 
 methods which the employer shall adopt ; and the state in- 
 surance commissioner has authority to determine the ade- 
 quacy and to regulate the compensation rates of the pri- 
 vate companies.^' 
 
 The State Accident Fund is a creature of the act.^* Full 
 permission is given to the commission to establish this fund 
 by the underwriting of insurance policies under the act. 
 The Maryland fund is in the nature of a straight insurance 
 scheme as contrasted with the compulsory, state-adminis- 
 tered mutual insurance fund of the Ohio act. The rules 
 for its administration, and its actual administration, are 
 based upon the experience and organization of private in- 
 
 "* Sees. 14 and 15. 
 
 '2 Sees. 15, 29, and 30. 
 
 '' See. 15, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 597; and Sec. 29. 
 
 '* See Sees. 16-28, as amended in 1916.
 
 66 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [212 
 
 surance companies. Full power to make rates and classifi- 
 cations conducive to accident prevention is granted. Penal 
 provisions allow the state fund to enforce certain regula- 
 tions as to uniform payrolls or payroll reports which the 
 private companies enforce by cancellation. As practically 
 conducted, the fund does not solicit policies ; and it has thus 
 been able to quote rates on the eight or nine hundred poli- 
 cies which it had underwritten at the end of 1916 ten to 
 thirty per cent lower than the private companies. This 
 saving is also due, in part, to the fact that for the first 
 three years the full cost of administration is borne by the 
 State ; and, even after the first three years, the fund is only 
 to bear that part of the expense which is proportionate to 
 its share of the policies written in the State.^^ It is, of 
 course, impossible to give prior to the lapse of a period of 
 five or possibly ten years an opinion of any value on the 
 efficiency or economy of the state fund, A principal ob- 
 jection to such a fund is that, being unable to refuse any 
 policy, it is oveYburdened with bad risks. Another objec- 
 tion is that the reserve is generally insufficient to cover 
 catastrophe risk, though in Maryland, it would seem, the 
 entire resources of the State are behind the fund.^^ Both 
 of these as affecting the possibility of the passing of pay- 
 ments are of utmost importance to the employee, more so 
 perhaps than to the employer. 
 
 The objections to the Maryland fund, it is obvious, are 
 due to the fact that it is elective and in competition with 
 the private companies. This fact has led other States, nota- 
 bly Ohio and Washington, to create a monopoly of insur- 
 ance in the state fund. The savings in administration 
 would seem a convincing argument for this mode of secur- 
 ity, if efficient administrative officers could be procured for 
 the state fund and the fund in its entirety could be kept out 
 of politics. This, of course, is socialistic legislation, and 
 encounters the opposition that is the natural concomitant 
 
 35 See Sec. 2j, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 597. 
 3« Sec. 16, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 597.
 
 213] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 6/ 
 
 of all socialistic enterprises. In Maryland, especially, this 
 opposition would be strong and effective because of the 
 great growth of Baltimore as a center of casualty insurance 
 companies and the consequent disruption of business which 
 would of necessity ensue. 
 
 The law as a whole is administered by the State Indus- 
 trial Accident Commission, composed of three commission- 
 ers appointed by the governor of the State for a term of 
 six years with an annual salary of five thousand dollars.^^ 
 Provision is made that this commission shall be bi-partisan, 
 but there is no attempt to secure efficient administration at 
 the cost of party politics. The commission has the employ- 
 ment of upwards of fifty clerks, actuaries, etc., with no 
 supervision except the written approval of the governor to 
 the salaries : competitive examinations are not mentioned. 
 During the administration of each governor the terms of 
 at least two of the three commissioners will expire so that 
 each governor will be able to change completely the political 
 complexion of a board which will annually spend forty 
 thousand dollars or over. Whether party politics is going 
 to spoil another good legislative endeavor, it is, of course, 
 impossible to prophesy; but it seems unpardonable that a 
 more efficient check than public opinion was not provided 
 in the law. 
 
 The principal, and, at this time,^* the only, office of the 
 commission is in Baltimore City ; but, when it is more con- 
 venient for one of the commissioners to go into another 
 part of the State to hold a hearing than it is for the claim- 
 ant with all his witnesses to travel to Baltimore, advantage 
 is taken of the provision allowing one commissioner to hold 
 hearings and make awards subject to the approval of his 
 
 '■^ Sees. I and 3. Three thousand dollars only of the salary is paid 
 by the State, because of the provision of the Constitution against 
 appointive officers with salaries above three thousand dollars (Art. 
 15, Sec. i). The other two thousand dollars is paid by the City of 
 Baltimore, a practice which has been recently approved by the Court 
 of Appeals with regard to the Public Service Commission in Thrift 
 V. Laird, 125 Md. 55. 
 
 88 1916.
 
 68 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2I4 
 
 colleagues. The normal course of proceedings, however, is 
 for the entire inquiry to be conducted at the home office by 
 the commission as a whole. When due notice has been 
 given of an accident and the fourteen waiting days have 
 passed, during which time the injured laborer has been 
 enjoying medical treatment, the commission sets a date five 
 days in advance, before which any objection to the pay- 
 ment of the claim must be made and a hearing requested. 
 Unless there is objection the claim is paid, for there is 
 specifically declared to be a strong presumption that " the 
 claim comes within the provisions of the act, that sufficient 
 notice was given, that the injury was not occasioned by the 
 wilful intention of the injured employee to bring about the 
 death or injury of himself or another, and that the injury 
 did not result solely from the intoxication of the injured 
 employee while on duty."^® It is in these summary cases 
 naturally that the principal economies of the law become 
 apparent. 
 
 If the employer demurs to the employees' claim, a hear- 
 ing is set. The hearing is held either before the Accident 
 Commission or before a special arbitration committee ap- 
 pointed by it.*" Until a large body of precedents is built 
 up it is not expected that a special arbitration committee 
 will be often appointed. At these hearings the commission 
 prefers to have each party represented by an attorney, so 
 that the case will be presented in an orderly manner. Here 
 becomes apparent one of the points where, in the practical 
 operation of a compensation law, it departs radically from 
 its ideals of no lawyers and no hostility between capital and 
 labor. The proceedings of the commission are, however, 
 fnost siunmary in their nature. There is no pleading ; com- 
 mon law rules of evidence do not prevail.*^ Only one of 
 the present commissioners is a lawyer, and the commis- 
 sioners often question the witness in order to bring out what 
 
 8* Sec. 62. 
 *° Sec. 40. 
 *^ Sees. 9-10.
 
 215] "^H^ workmen's compensation law 69 
 
 seem to them essential points. The proceedings should be 
 equitable rather than legal in nature has declared a Massa- 
 chusetts court in a recent decision.*^ In all investigations 
 the commission has " power to issue subpoenas, compel the 
 attendance of witnesses, . . . compel the production of 
 pertinent books, payrolls, accounts, papers, records, docu- 
 ments and testimony," and an immunity bath is provided 
 against self-incrimination to save the constitutionality of 
 the statute.*^ Every precaution is taken to secure swift 
 and adequate justice and to make this board, though quasi- 
 Judicial in its procedure, executive in its action. The pow- 
 ers of the commission do not cease upon each award, but 
 continue like the powers of equity courts over their trustees 
 and guardians : it may at any time upon due cause and 
 notice amend its awards and decisions.** 
 
 "Any employer, employee, beneficiary or person feeling 
 aggrieved by any decision of the commission affecting his 
 interests under this Act may have the same reviewed by a 
 proceeding in the nature of an appeal " in any common law 
 court having jurisdiction; "and the court shall determine 
 whether the commission has justly considered all the facts 
 concerning the injury, whether it has exceeded the powers 
 granted it by the Act, or whether it has misconstrued the 
 law and facts applicable in the case decided." This appeal 
 also is to be conducted in a summary manner, but, upon 
 motion of either party, any question of fact involved may 
 be submitted to a jury. Appeals from these proceedings lie 
 to the Court of Appeals.*^ 
 
 This exposition of the principles of the act demonstrates 
 that it is a piece of legislation passed for the benefit of the 
 laborer; and, insufficient and unsatisfactory as some of its 
 
 ^2 In re Mut. Liability Ins. Co., 102 N. E. 693. 
 
 *3 Sec. 7. Contempt of any of these orders may be punished upon 
 application to any judge in Maryland. 
 
 ** Sec. 54. Construed in Adleman v. Ocean Accident, etc. Corp., 
 130 Md. 512. 
 
 *5 Sec. 56. See also Breuner v. Breuner, 127 Md. 189; Frazier v. 
 Leas, 127 Md. 572.
 
 yO THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2l6 
 
 provisions have been found to be, it brings about a great 
 improvement over previous conditions. Besides its effect 
 as social legislation, however, certain legal results follow 
 from its enactment. 
 
 The Constitutionality of the Law. — From the legal stand- 
 point, the most interesting feature of a compensation law is 
 its constitutionality. Frankly considered, the law requires 
 that the money of one set of people shall be handed over 
 irrespective of fault to the members of another class upon 
 the happening of a contingency. Such a law is a new de- 
 parture in American legislation and presents some ex- 
 tremely interesting constitutional questions. Numerous ar- 
 guments, brilliant and intricate, have been published in sup- 
 port of the constitutionality of the law, so that here there 
 is need only of a mere outline of the difficulties. 
 
 The fact that the compensation law substitutes vicarious 
 liability without reference to fault for the old common law 
 liability is thus met: "Our jurisprudence affords many ex- 
 amples of legal liability without fault and the deprivation of 
 property without fault being attributable to its owner. The 
 law of deodands was such an example. . . . Other exam- 
 ples are afforded in the liability of the husband for the torts 
 of his wife — the liability of a master for the acts of his 
 servants."*® Statutes furnish further examples. Munici- 
 palities have been made responsible for property destroyed 
 by a mob;*'^ railroads have been made liable for damage 
 caused by sparks from its engines.*^ But these precedents 
 are not precedents for the compensation law. The common 
 law instances cited are merely the result of imputing to one 
 the fault of another whose action he controls, and the stat- 
 utes relate to special objects of state activity. Compensa- 
 tion laws, on the other hand, make an innocent employer 
 carrying on a private, lawful business liable even for an 
 accident occurring in the course of that business. This 
 
 « Chicago, R. I. & R. R. Co. v. Zernicke, 183 U. S. 582. 
 *^ Chicago V. Sturgis, 222 U. S. 313. 
 
 «st. Louis, S. F. R. Co. v. Mathews, 165 U. S. i, and numerous 
 state decisions.
 
 21/] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW /I 
 
 argument through precedents does not lead to very satis- 
 factory conclusions. 
 
 Another argument seeks to uphold the compensation law 
 upon the basis of the decision in the Second Employers' 
 Liability case.*® This decision held that it was within the 
 power of Congress so to change the rules of law that no 
 railroad could avail itself of the three common law de- 
 fences of assumption of risk, contributory negligence, and 
 fellow-servant doctrine in a damage suit against it by an 
 employee. The decision merely reiterated the old opinion 
 that there can be no property in a rule of law.^° To try to 
 base the constitutionality of the compensation law upon 
 this decision displays an ignorance of the distinction between 
 that law and an employers' liability law. The liability law 
 merely abrogates the three common law defences and leaves 
 the law of industrial accidents otherwise the same; the 
 compensation law provides for the indiscriminate indemni- 
 fication by an administrative tribunal of all industrial acci- 
 dents. The liability law retains the idea of fault ; the com- 
 pensation law imposes a vicarious liability. 
 
 A final case relied upon — and this time with more justi- 
 fication — is the bank guarantee case.^^ Here the court held 
 constitutional a law which ordered all state banks in the 
 State of Oklahoma to contribute to a guarantee fund from 
 which were to be paid the losses sustained by the deposit- 
 ors in any state bank by its insolvency. Here property is 
 taken from one set of people to be handed over to another 
 set upon the happening of a contingency for which the first 
 set is often without fault. In this respect this law is ex- 
 actly similar to a compensation law, and this case, especially 
 in view of the broad language used by Justice Holmes, is 
 most aptly referred to as a precedent and an analogue in 
 arguing the constitutionality of a compensation law. But a 
 distinction can be drawn. In the first place, banking is 
 
 « Mundou V. N. Y., N. H. & H. R. Co., 223 U. S. I. 
 
 ''o Munn V. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113. 
 
 " Noble State Bank v. Haskell, 219 U. S. 104.
 
 72 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2 1 8 
 
 peculiarly a subject of state control; it is most highly 
 "aflfected with a public interest." In fact, it is really a 
 public business entrusted to private enterprise and almost 
 any regulation in furtherance of the public welfare would 
 be justified. In the second place, there is a decided com- 
 munity of interest among bankers which tends to make them 
 stand together and be somewhat responsible for the acts of 
 one another, so that the law merely lends the sanction of 
 the state to what was before demanded by self-interest. It 
 might be argued that a compensation law creates a com- 
 munity of interest among employers in the promotion of 
 safety, but this is a difficult argument, and there is of course 
 no special public interest in most of the occupations covered 
 by a compensation law. Therefore, though the bank guar- 
 antee case is a weighty precedent, it does not seem to be 
 absolutely conclusive. 
 
 If a compulsory compensation law is to be frankly up- 
 held, it will have to be upheld as an exercise of the police 
 power. It was in the exercise of this power that the Mary- 
 land act was avowedly passed.^^ " * Property of every kind 
 — it must be remembered — is held subject to those regula- 
 tions which are necessary for the common good and general 
 welfare. And the legislature has the power to define the 
 mode and manner in which every one may use his prop- 
 erty.' "^^ It is in pursuance of this power, as was said in 
 the first chapter, that all labor legislation is enacted and, if 
 we consider the previous, admittedly constitutional labor 
 enactments, it will be easily demonstrated that the compen- 
 sation law is merely a peculiar development of a well- 
 established principle. 
 
 Since the Industrial Revolution, the bargaining power of 
 the laborer has not been equal to that of the employer. 
 The inequality was early recognized by the legislatures and 
 
 ^"^ See the preamble, Part 4. 
 
 53 Windsor v. State, 103 Md. 611, quoting Story on the Constitu- 
 tion. See also Singer v. State, 72 Md. 464; State v. Hyman, 98 Md. 
 596; 64 L. R. A. 637 ; State v. Gurry, 121 Md. 534; C. & P. Telephone 
 Co. V. Board of Forestry, 125 Md. 666.
 
 219] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 73 
 
 the courts too have now explicitly sanctioned the legislative 
 correction of this inequality."^* In pursuance of this policy 
 of equalization, the legislatures have never seen fit to make 
 absolutely equal the two parties to the labor contract, but 
 have instead guaranteed to the employee certain terms of 
 the contract which were conceived as necessary to the " gen- 
 eral welfare and public convenience." Thus the legislature 
 has passed child labor laws, hours of labor laws for men 
 and women, safety and sanitation laws, and a host of other 
 laws which are not so easy of classification. The compen- 
 sation law is a law of this kind. Conceiving that the em- 
 ployee could not successfully bargain with the employer for 
 a sufficient insurance to himself against industrial accidents, 
 the legislature by its fiat introduced such an insurance term 
 into every labor contract. That is to say, the law recognized 
 that, as economists had long contended, the employee did 
 not visualize all the risks of his employment, as the com- 
 mon law assumed he did, and demand a higher wage in con- 
 sequence thereof. Therefore, says the law, an implied term 
 of every contract shall be an adequate compensation in case 
 of industrial accident. 
 
 That this term of the contract is as necessary to the gen- 
 eral welfare as are the terms introduced by previous laws 
 seems hardly to require detailed proof. Indus^trial acci- 
 dents are undoubtedly the principal causes of poverty and 
 degradation. If the prevention of poverty is not necessary 
 to the general welfare of a community, what is ? It is true 
 that the courts, not however without criticism, have re- 
 fused to sanction taxation for the prevention of poverty. 
 But, granting the correctness of these decisions, they do not 
 weaken our argument. By a compensation law the State 
 does not tax for the prevention of destitution; it merely 
 decrees that industry shall not prosper from the mishaps 
 of the employee, just as it formerly declared that industry 
 should not prosper from the labor of children. Industry 
 must be conducted legitimately and it is certainly within 
 
 " Holden v. Hardy, 169 U. S. 366.
 
 74 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [220 
 
 the power of the State to decree that industry shall bear 
 the cost of all its materials, the cost of the life and limbs of 
 its laborers, as well as of the inanimate equipment and raw 
 stuffs. 
 
 In thus briefly outlining the constitutional difficulties 
 which accompany a compensation law, it is of course im- 
 possible to consider the finer points of law. Equally im- 
 possible is it to examine some minor constitutional ques- 
 tions which may be raised with regard to the Maryland 
 law, but which are not essential to the compensation prin- 
 ciple. 
 
 From the practical legal standpoint, the most important 
 result of the compensation law will be to render obsolete 
 in the occupations covered all the intricate tort law dealing 
 with the relation between employer and employee."^" As 
 has been so often iterated, the employer can no longer plead 
 contributory negligence, the doctrine of assumption of risk, 
 and the fellow servant doctrine in defense of a claim 
 against him by an employee. The law of contributory 
 negligence will continue to exist in other damage suits, but 
 with this exception these doctrines will ultimately pass out 
 of existence. With them will pass a mass of complicated 
 and unsettled law. No longer will there be a question of 
 what risks the employee assumes on entering an employ- 
 ment, of what kinds of instruments the employer must fur- 
 nish, whether a defect in a machine is latent or patent, or 
 whether the employer has engaged efficient fellow servants 
 to work with the employee. No longer, in short, will it be 
 necessary to enumerate the duties of the employer to the 
 employee, for they will all become merged in one duty, — 
 to compensate him for an industrial accident. No longer 
 again will it be necessary to determine who are fellow ser- 
 vants, for the doctrine relating to them is also abolished. 
 By an amendment of 1916 one of the elaborations of this 
 rule is explicitly abrogated. If an employee of a subcon- 
 tractor is injured he may collect his compensation directly 
 
 65 See Harlan, Domestic Relations, Part V.
 
 22 1] THE workmen's COMPENSATION LAW 75 
 
 from the contractor in chief, who will then contest with 
 the subcontractor the ultimate liability.'^ Thus, so far as 
 the working-man is concerned, the doctrine of independent 
 contractor and with it the doctrine of vice-principal is 
 abolished. 
 
 In place of this branch of the law there is growing up a 
 new series of cases deciding what is an accidental injury 
 " arising out of " and " in the course of employment." This 
 line of cases, if we can judge from present indications, 
 threatens to become as long as those which have been over- 
 thrown by the act ; but they will hardly result in such diffi- 
 cult law. I have already quoted the definition adopted by 
 the Maryland Accident Commission. 
 
 Finally a change must be noted in the relation of the em- 
 ployee to the insurance carrier. Under the common law the 
 insurance carrier bears no special relation to the employee ; 
 it was merely the indemnifier of the employer. Under the 
 compensation law " the insurance carrier occupies the posi- 
 tion of surety for the employer, to secure the fulfillment of 
 any liability which may be determined to have arisen."^'^ 
 The liability of the carrier to the employee is a primary lia- 
 bility jointly with the employer, and it is not excused from 
 payment of the compensation by the bankruptcy or insol- 
 vency of the employer.^^ Nor, of course, on the other hand 
 is the employer relieved by insuring in a bankrupt or in- 
 solvent insurance carrier. 
 
 s« Laws 1916, Ch. 597, adding Sec. 60A to the Code. 
 5^^ Brenner v. Brenner, 127 Md. 189. 
 68 Code 1914, Art. loi, Sec. 36.
 
 CHAPTER IV 
 The Conditions of Employment 
 
 The enactments of the state regulating the conditions of 
 employment of the workingman, the safety and sanitation 
 laws, are the most important features of a constructive 
 labor legislation program. True, the activity of the state 
 in the fields discussed in the two preceding chapters is most 
 essential to the welfare of the laborer, but the statutes re- 
 lating to the labor union and the compensation law are for 
 the most part amendatory of the common law. Such inter- 
 ference of the state in labor matters was directed to making 
 more efficient the existing means for the reform of labor 
 conditions, that is, to the development of the union and to 
 the modernizing of the common law to fit present day in- 
 dustrial conditions ; the remainder of this study will be con- 
 cerned with the extent to which the state should intervene 
 in private affairs in the attempt to ameliorate labor condi- 
 tions. 
 
 The most important matter with regard to which the 
 state exercises its power of intervention is the regulation of 
 the environment in which the laborer conducts his daily 
 task. This dogmatic statement might be strenuously con- 
 tested by some labor reform advocates and by some econ- 
 omists, but their position seems to be much weakened by 
 an unproportioned estimate of present conditions and future 
 possibilities. The contention that the foremost problems 
 and concerns of labor are unemployment, wages and hours 
 may be admitted without disproving the contention that the 
 prime object of state activity is the safeguarding of the 
 employee in his daily work. Not only historically was this 
 the first concern of the state in industrial conditions, but 
 practically it affects more intimately and more uniformly 
 
 76
 
 223] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 7/ 
 
 the whole mass of workingmen. State employment officers 
 may find work for a part of the unemployed who rarely 
 comprise more than eight per cent of the working class ; the 
 state may set a minimum wage for the hopelessly weak bar- 
 gainers; and the state may regulate hours in the extremely 
 overworked trades ; but, in all these, the great majority of 
 the workers are working out their own salvation with con- 
 stantly increasing success. Safety and sanitary legislation, 
 on the other hand, affects every laborer. The unit of re- 
 form, so to speak, is the factory, not the individual; and it 
 is this distinction which brings these factory laws peculiarly 
 within the function of the state and takes them out of the 
 scope of private and voluntary means of reform. 
 
 It is hardly necessary at this late date to argue that safety 
 and sanitation legislation is proper in the present status of 
 industrial conditions. Not even the most extreme adherent 
 of laissez-faire can deny that competition and the absence 
 of regulation reduce the conditions of labor below the 
 standards of decency and good health. Even the most ex- 
 treme individualists admit that the police power of the state 
 extends to the reasonable regulation of working conditions. 
 Only the opposition of the capitalist, who naturally objects 
 to the expenditure of his money for the benefit of others, 
 and that without any easily perceptible advantage to him- 
 self, deters the legislators from enacting the fine, ideal laws 
 which have been drafted for them. 
 
 Regulation by Commission. — There is, however, some 
 dispute with reference to the preferable mode of regulation 
 if not to the necessity and kind of regulation. Until five 
 years ago all safety and sanitary laws, if complete, were 
 lengthy, minute enactments covering every known condition 
 of employment and laying down absolute laws to apply to 
 every preconceived condition. Set screws, unguarded belts, 
 and other dangerous devices were absolutely outlawed, but 
 there the law stopped. In 191 1 Wisconsin,^ drawing a les- 
 
 ^ Wisconsin Laws, Sees. 2304-41 to 2394-71.
 
 78 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [224 
 
 son from the evolution of the governmental control of rates, 
 applied the commission idea of regulation to industrial con- 
 ditions. A general law providing for safety in industrial 
 occupations was enacted and a commission with ordinance 
 powers was appointed to issue orders in compliance with 
 this general law. Full discretionary powers are substituted 
 for absolute and arbitrary regulation. Finding it impossi- 
 ble to foresee every possible contingency in which the labor 
 law would be applied and conceiving it equally impossible 
 to leave anything to the easily corrupted discretion of the 
 inspectors, the legislature created a competent and respon- 
 sible board to carry out its wishes. The idea of this fourth 
 branch of government, the administrative branch, as it is 
 sometimes called,^ is not new in American politics. The 
 federal government has found it advisable in handling in- 
 terstate commercial and industrial conditions and the State 
 governments have rather generally adopted the same means 
 of controlling their public service corporations and of ad- 
 ministering their workmen's compensation laws. In the 
 field of labor legislation the experiment of Wisconsin has 
 not failed to stimulate imitation; both Massachusetts and 
 New York among the Eastern States having to a consider- 
 able degree adopted this means of regulation. 
 
 From the legal standpoint the commission is an investi- 
 gating agency with, it is true, considerably more power to 
 secure practical benefits from its investigations than have 
 most investigating committees. The significance of this 
 aspect of the commission's work is most obvious. As has 
 been said, the regulation of the environment of employ:- 
 ment is easily within the police power of the state — the 
 protection of health and safety is the most elemental exer- 
 cise of this power. The only limitation upon this control is 
 that it must be reasonable both in the manner of its appli- 
 
 2 Most of this discussion of the industrial commission scheme of 
 government has been suggested by an article by J. R. Commons, 
 published by the Wisconsin Industrial Commission, most of which 
 appeared m The Survey for January 4, 1913.
 
 225] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 79 
 
 cation and in the discrimination necessarily involved in its 
 exercise. Because of the manner in which the commission 
 formulates its rules, its ordinances have the prima facie 
 weight of reasonableness greater than in the case of legis- 
 lative enactments. 
 
 The commission is assisted in drawing up its orders by 
 unpaid, advisory subcommittees on the various subjects of 
 safety and sanitation. These subcommittees are not com- 
 posed of experts fixing ideal regulations, which, as Mr. 
 Commons says, may be reasonable in a superregulated coun- 
 try like Germany, but hardly in the United States ; they are 
 where possible drawn mainly from the ranks of the em- 
 ployers and employees, with occasionally one or two ex- 
 perts who are usually taken from state boards or insurance 
 companies. These subcommittees deliberate, hear witnesses 
 in the same manner as legislative committees, and draw up 
 rules which are referred to the commission as "general 
 orders." These orders are published and then considered at 
 hearings held before the commission. If amendments are 
 suggested to the commission at these hearings and approved 
 by them the report of the advisors is recommitted to them. 
 When finally approved by the commission, the "general 
 orders " are enacted to go into effect thirty days after final 
 publication. The orders can, of course, be attacked in 
 court ; but, as the commission has sat at its hearings in its 
 judicial capacity its findings are presumed to be reasonable 
 and constitutional, and even if before the court new evi- 
 dence is unearthed to prove the unreasonableness of the 
 order the order is referred back to the commission for a 
 rehearing; the court does not absolutely annul the order. 
 Moreover, since these orders are adopted by a body com- 
 posed largely of employers, little ground is afforded for the 
 objection of arbitrariness and public opinion has a strong 
 lever against the recalcitrant capitalist. 
 
 Moreover, through its power to enforce the factory law, 
 to control inspection and to enact " special orders " to fit 
 unforeseen contingencies, the commission is enabled to ad-
 
 8o THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [226 
 
 minister the law more efficiently and some would be tempted 
 to say more humanely than it otherwise could. As the com- 
 mission itself characterizes this part of its work, "the work 
 of the inspectors of the commission is not to ferret out 
 points of danger and to tabulate them, but it is chiefly to do 
 constructive educational work. . . . The one point which 
 the commissioners most strongly emphasize with the depu- 
 ties is that they must so present safety work that the em- 
 ployers will become interested and will appreciate its prac- 
 tical value from the standpoint of efficiency."^ The field 
 agents of the commission are " deputies," not "inspectors." 
 They confer with each employer and if there is an excep- 
 tional situation in his plant, a " special order " is obtained 
 from the commission to prevent any irritation from the 
 operation of the general orders. The same principles un- 
 derlie the educational work of the commission among tho 
 employees, for it is well recognized that safety results quitfi 
 as much from the improved esprit de corps of the workers 
 as from mechanical safety devices. 
 
 In short, everything reasonable is done to decrease the 
 enormous loss of life and limb which had come to be con- 
 sidered a natural concomitant of modem industry. " Rea- 
 sonableness " may be said to be the watchword of the com- 
 mission. The effect of its policy has been to reduce irrita- 
 tion and to keep the factory law out of the courts. It seems 
 beyond doubt that this plan of legislation will be held con- 
 stitutional, for the courts have recognized this fourth branch 
 of government in other fields ; and once the legality of the 
 fundamental law is established there can hardly be further 
 dispute with reference to an order enacted as these orders 
 are. Moreover, the new status of the inspection depart- 
 ment will keep most cases out of court, for it is human 
 nature to respond more readily to solicitous appeals than 
 to threatening commands. In fact, it has been found in 
 Wisconsin that once an intelligent employer has been shown 
 
 « Report of the Wisconsin Industrial Commission on Allied Func- 
 bons for the Two Years Ending June 30, 1914, p. 9.
 
 227] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 8 1 
 
 the most evident deficiencies of his establishment, his own 
 sense of justice will often prompt him to undertake a thor- 
 ough rehabilitation of his plant. 
 
 In Maryland, however, this scheme has not obtained any 
 considerable foothold, and, though it is instructive to ex- 
 amine it in a purely disinterested spirit as a more efficient 
 system to which we are inevitably tending, yet such a study 
 does not take us far in the investigation of the existing laws, 
 Maryland, however, is woefully deficient in its factory leg- 
 islation ; and, even in studying the existing laws, this chap- 
 ter will be as often a consideration of ideals as of actual 
 facts. 
 
 Fire Protection. — The fire hazard can without doubt be 
 said to be the most important safety problem demanding 
 solution by the State at the present day. Yet practically 
 every State, unless it has adopted a new building code, 
 within the last few years has taken decidedly inadequate 
 measures to meet the danger. Maryland is no exception. 
 Despite the general agreement that "an ounce of preven- 
 tion is worth a pound of cure," the legislature of Maryland 
 allows every city and county within its bounds to expend 
 thousands in maintaining an elaborate fire department and, 
 with the exception of the City of Baltimore, provides no 
 fire prevention law. Even in Baltimore the laws and ordi- 
 nances aimed at the prevention of fire are not at all in 
 proportion to the hazard. It needs a tragedy to arouse the 
 American public to action and, because as yet there has been 
 no holocaust in Baltimore, we are content to await one be- 
 fore enacting the proper laws. 
 
 Practically the entire fire law of Baltimore and, in con- 
 sidering this subject, Baltimore will take the place of Mary- 
 land as the unit of discussion since the fire hazard has been 
 considered important enough for legislation only in this 
 city — practically the entire fire law of Baltimore is in the 
 hands of the building inspector. Now, at the beginning of 
 this chapter, the excellencies of an elastic law were ex- 
 tolled ; but the fire law is one wherein certain fundamental 
 6
 
 82 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [228 
 
 maxims and orders can be laid down with precision, and 
 have been laid down in states where legislation has been 
 carefully enacted, as in New York. Moreover, when the 
 law is elastic it should be administered by a competent com- 
 mission imder some pressure to enact orders and not by the 
 arbitrary will of one political appointee to office. Of the 
 fire laws affecting places of labor which do not depend 
 upon the discretion of the inspector, one forbids the "pro- 
 prietor of any sweatshop or factory where four or more 
 persons are employed to use any coal oil, gasoline, etc. . . . 
 for the purpose of lighting or heating in any form."* Not 
 only is this the only absolute provision of the fire law, but, 
 as far as I can discover, it is the only provision looking to 
 fire prevention and not to fire escape. Another law does in 
 a way provide a barrier against fire in decreeing the fire- 
 proof construction of the first floor of buildings to be built 
 after 1906;^ but this fire prevention is in the nature of a 
 protection to the physical structure of the workshop and not 
 to the lives of the workers, for experience has demonstrated 
 that, as far as human life is concerned, fireproof buildings 
 are as dangerous to those in the buildings as non-fireproof 
 structures. 
 
 These two laws also provide for a means of escape ; and 
 in this respect are of value, but being incomplete these pro- 
 visions are less important than those which have just been 
 considered. In the latter law it is ordered that, in all new 
 buildings, "the entire stairway shall be built of fireproof 
 material," but as the best fire escape is often useless if it 
 is open to the inroads of smoke and flame, the omission to 
 provide for a fireproof enclosure around the escape robs 
 this portion of the law of most of its value. The earlier 
 law commands fire escapes in sweatshops or factories 
 " where four or more persons are employed as garment 
 workers on other than the first floor " of the building. The 
 qualification of garment worker is, of course, pernicious ; 
 
 * Laws 1898, Ch. 123 ; Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 4, Sec. 28a 
 ^ Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 3, Sec. 82.
 
 229] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 83 
 
 and it is alleged that this provision of the building code is 
 further weakened by the arbitrary interpretation of the 
 word fire escape by the building inspector whose require- 
 ments are met by one unenclosed fireproof staircase or even 
 by two wooden staircases in separate parts of the building." 
 
 The other laws enforced by the building inspector are 
 even more lax and inefficient, and they are to a certain de- 
 gree overlapping and confusing. One provides that " all 
 manufactories employing twenty-five or more persons . . . 
 [shall] have the proper means of exit in case of fire or 
 panic " in the discretion of the inspector of buildings.'^ An 
 ordinance of the mayor and City Council of Baltimore 
 makes the same stipulation for buildings in which five or 
 more are employed f and a final provision decrees that any 
 building " in which operatives are employed in any of the 
 stories above the first story shall be provided with such fire 
 escapes, alarms and doors as shall be directed and approved 
 by the inspector of buildings."^ This ofiicial has issued few 
 orders of any importance. 
 
 The whole situation is unsatisfactory. The fire code is 
 incomplete and far below the requirements of a modern 
 industrial city. It is true that there has been no astounding 
 loss of life in any fire in Baltimore, but this must be due 
 more to individual endeavor than to State supervision ; and, 
 moreover, the per capita monetary loss in Baltimore is still 
 oppressively high as compared with European cities and the 
 foremost American cities. A systematic revision of the fire 
 law should be undertaken. In this respect Baltimore might 
 profit by the experience of New York. After the terrible 
 Triangle Waist fire. New York with the aid of the Factory 
 Investigating Commission devised and to a great degree 
 enacted a complete system of fire laws.^° This system, 
 
 « Miss Anna Herkner, then Assistant Chief of Maryland Bureau 
 of Statistics, is the authority for this statement. See also report of 
 this Bureau for 1912, p. 75. 
 
 '' Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 3, Sec. 80. 
 
 * Ordinances 1908-1909, No. 155, Sec. 3, Par. 6. 
 
 8 Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 3, Sec. 83. 
 
 1° See New York Senate Documents 1913, vol. 13, no. 36, pt. i, pp. 
 S;^-89; and New York Consolidated Laws, Ch. 31, Sees. 79-83-
 
 84 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [23O 
 
 though in its details entirely too stringent for the necessi- 
 ties of Baltimore, might well be adopted in its fundamentals 
 in this city. As a prevention against fire, cleanliness and 
 carefulness are the two essentials. Fireproof receptacles 
 should, therefore, be required for all inflammable waste and 
 rubbish, and these receptacles should be emptied at least 
 once a day. Gas jets in factories should be enclosed by 
 globes or otherwise protected and all smoking in factories 
 should be prohibited under penalty. Furthermore, to check 
 incipient fires automatic sprinklers should be installed. 
 These, the New York commission says, are absolutely nec- 
 essary above the seventh floor on account of the limitations 
 of the fire fighting apparatus, but these limitations do not 
 trouble us much in Baltimore for the simple reason that 
 few of our factories are over six stories in height. For the 
 benefit of the factory owner, it may be said that these 
 sprinklers have proved their worth in from seventy-five 
 to ninety-five per cent of the cases in which they have been 
 tested by actual conditions, and that, moreover, they pay 
 for themselves in reduced insurance rates. 
 
 For the protection of those caught within the building 
 by a fire the commission formulated minute and elaborate 
 rules. A fire alarm system, for which in Maryland there is 
 an inadequate provision, and regularly conducted fire drills 
 participated in by all the occupants of the building are con- 
 ceived as a prime essential to avert panics. Unhampered 
 and quick access to the exits on the various floors is also 
 a desideratum which is so often sacrificed to the demands 
 for space. For the fire escapes themselves elaborate rules 
 are laid down. In the first place, outside escapes are uni- 
 formly discouraged. These escapes are practically of little 
 use, for the inmates are not accustomed to use them; and 
 if in a panic a few find them these few are often too be- 
 wildered to use them efficiently. Moreover, in winter the 
 outside escapes are often slippery, and the smoke and flames 
 pouring out of a window opening on them render them en- 
 tirely useless. The most efficient escapes are horizontal
 
 231] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 85 
 
 exits through a fire wall traversing the whole length of the 
 building from ground to roof. This divides the structure 
 into two fireproof compartments and, it is perfectly obvi- 
 ous, furnishes an ideal means of escape. If this is imprac- 
 ticable the same end may be attained by the cooperative use 
 by two buildings of the party wall. An enclosed fireproof 
 staircase within or attached to the building is another ap- 
 proved method of escape and if large enough, this staircase 
 is perfectly efficient. The New York building code fur- 
 nishes minute regulations as to the relation of the number 
 of occupants to the width of the various kinds of fire es- 
 capes, but what has been said is sufficient to show the mag- 
 nitude of the improvement possible and necessary in 
 Maryland. 
 
 Protective Devices. — In its provisions for the safeguard- 
 ing of dangerous machines the Maryland labor law is, if 
 anything, more deficient than its provisions against fire. 
 There are a few laws decreeing the inspection of scaffold- 
 ing^^ and boilers^^ with provisions for their safety, but that 
 is about all. There are, it is true, some general provisions 
 on the statute books, but these, though they might be most 
 prolific and efficient, are for the most part entirely abortive. 
 Thus in the compensation law^^ reference is made to the 
 power of the Accident Commission to order safety devices 
 in the factories ; but as yet this power has not been exer- 
 cised, and even if it were, the exercise would possibly be 
 unconstitutional because of the lack of notice in the title of 
 the act. Again, the building inspector has the power to com- 
 pel the repair or reconstruction of parts of buildings which 
 "endanger the safety of their occupants,"" and under his 
 power to issue permits for electrical machines^^ he may 
 compel the use of safety devices ; but these provisions have 
 been bootless. These deficiencies in Maryland are especially 
 
 11 Code 191 1, Art. 48, Sees. 75-79. 
 
 12 Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sees. 572-589- 
 
 13 Laws 1914, Ch. 800, Sec. 54. Code 1914, Art. loi, Sec. 55- 
 
 14 Baltimore City Ordinances 190S-1909, No. 155, Sec. 3, Par. 7. 
 « Baltimore City Code 1906, Ords. Art. 3, Sec. 45-
 
 86 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [232 
 
 glaring when it is remembered that Wisconsin and Massa- 
 chusetts by means of orders from their industrial commis- 
 sions and New York by means of legislative enactments 
 and orders have formulated an elaborate system of safety 
 regulations for the benefit of their working people. 
 
 Under the head of safety devices, though here the per- 
 sonal rather than the material element is concerned, may 
 be mentioned the full-crew railroad law.^® This, however, 
 the railroads have demonstrated to be not a valid safety 
 measure, but a mere sop to the unions. 
 
 Requiring the same brief mention, but actually of much 
 more importance, are the safety and inspection provisions 
 for mines in Alleghany and Garrett counties.^^ These are 
 minute and technical provisions, an extended discussion of 
 which would hardly lend interest to this study. The details 
 are most technical and quite beyond the comprehension of 
 a layman. Suffice it to say that the coal mines of Maryland 
 are considered as safe as any in the country, but whether 
 that is because of these enactments or because of the in- 
 herent nature of the mines would require an investigation 
 quite beyond the scope of this monograph. 
 
 Sanitation. — In the field of sanitary legislation the statute 
 book of Maryland until the legislative session of 1914 was 
 equally deficient. In that year special laws regulating tene- 
 ment houses and food-producing establishments set rather 
 high standards in those particular fields, but left the gen- 
 eral law totally inadequate. There was prior to 1914 a 
 general law providing that "all factories, etc. ... in this 
 State shall be kept in a cleanly condition and free from 
 effluvia arising from any drain, privy or other nuisance ; and 
 no factory, manufacturing establishment or workshop shall 
 be so overcrowded while work is carried on therein as to 
 be injurious to the health of the persons employed therein, 
 and every such factory, etc., shall be well and sufficiently 
 
 "Code 1911, Art. 23, Sees. 331-335. 
 
 "Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art. I, Sees. 207-209; Art. 12, 
 Sec. 161-164.
 
 233] ^^^ CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 8/ 
 
 lighted and ventilated in such manner as to render harm- 
 less, as far as practical, all gases, etc., generated in the 
 course of the process . . . carried on therein, which may 
 be injurious to health " ;^^ but the Bureau of Industrial Sta- 
 tistics and Inspection to which by means of a court pro- 
 ceeding was entrusted the enforcement of this law found it 
 absolutely impracticable because of the generality of its pro- 
 visions. It was impossible to convict in any court of justice : 
 an essential of a criminal statute is definiteness. The legis- 
 lature in 1914 repealed this law, and substituted therefor 
 a law requiring the licensing of all places manufacturing 
 "articles of clothing, hats, gloves, furs, feathers, artificial 
 flowers, purses, cigars or cigarettes. "^^ The only condition 
 precedent to the grant of this license is the necessity of a 
 minimum of five hundred cubic feet of air space for every 
 person employed — a necessary provision, but not of highly 
 practical value — and the compliance with the existing laws 
 and ordinances applying to these workshops. The real pur- 
 pose of this law as acknowledged by its sponsors, the indus- 
 trial bureau, was not to efifect an improvement of labor 
 conditions, but to show matters in their true light, to ex- 
 pose the real status of factory regulation, to relieve the 
 Board of Labor of the responsibility of enforcing a practi- 
 cally nonexistent law and to shift this responsibility to the 
 city officials who have the real means of coercion. 
 
 This law, it is obvious, is merely an additional means of 
 enforcing the general laws of the State in these specified 
 industries. There is, however, no general enactment in 
 Maryland applying throughout the State ; the nearest ap- 
 proach to a general sanitary provision is an ordinance of 
 Baltimore City decreeing separate toilets for the sexes to 
 be kept " in a cleanly and safe condition. "^^ Therefore, if 
 an industry is not located in a dwelling or tenement house, 
 if it is not engaged in manufacturing food products, and 
 
 18 Laws 1884, Ch, 265. Code 1904, Art. 27, Sec. 243. 
 18 Laws 1914, Ch. 779, Sec. 246. 
 
 18 Laws 1884, Ch, 265. Code 1904, Art. 27, Se 
 
 18 Laws 1914, Ch. 779, Sec. 246. 
 
 20 Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 14, Sec. 158.
 
 88 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [234 
 
 if it is not in Baltimore City, it has to comply with abso- 
 lutely no sanitary regulations, and, indeed, in these non- 
 regulated industries the sanitary condition has been found 
 to be very poor. No provision is made for the cleanliness 
 of factories, an essential to good health as well as to fire 
 protection. No provision is made for ventilation, a matter 
 which is the subject of numerous administrative orders in 
 other States. Not only is the ventilation of factories left 
 to private enterprise, but the slight provision that there is 
 for toilets does not provide for their ventilation and factory 
 toilets are very generally ventilated through the work rooms 
 of the factory. Only in Carroll County^^ is there any pro- 
 vision for a forced ventilation by suction fans to preserve 
 the workers from lung diseases brought on by inhaling dust 
 and noxious gases. To be entirely fair, the law requiring 
 the sprinkling of the floors of shirt factories every morn- 
 ing22 should be mentioned here, but the relief is so slight 
 and the method is so antiquated that this narrowly limited 
 law cannot greatly mitigate the indictment of Maryland. 
 Finally, if we omit consideration of minor requirements, 
 there is in Maryland no law looking to the proper lighting 
 of factories ; and the employer is at full liberty to strain 
 the eyesight of his workers to the point of exhaustion. Al- 
 though I have not made a thorough investigation at first 
 hand, some of the actual conditions described I have myself 
 observed ; and if some first hand investigator seeks to ex- 
 tenuate these failings of the Maryland law by maintaining 
 that actual conditions demonstrate on the whole that Mary- 
 land does not as yet need regulatory laws, I would answer 
 that it is always easier to prohibit by legislation things 
 which are not in existence and which do not represent as 
 yet any vested right. Inasmuch, moreover, as other States 
 have had to cope with these evils, now is the time for Mary- 
 land to legislate. 
 
 In decided contrast to this inefficient phase of the law is 
 
 21 Laws 1894, Ch. 202. Applies only to stone-grinding mills. 
 
 22 Code 191 1, Art. 43, Sec. 102.
 
 235] "^^^ CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 89 
 
 the recently enacted sanitary inspection law." The act 
 makes minute provision for the regulation of every place 
 in which " food products are manufactured, packed, stored, 
 deposited, collected, prepared, produced or sold."-* In ad- 
 dition there is vested in the State Board of Health, which 
 is entrusted with the administration of the law, full power 
 to promulgate, " from time to time, . . . such general rules 
 and regulations . . . for the government of the inspectors 
 and employees of the board as may be necessary," provided 
 it gives due notice of these orders with the opportunity of 
 a hearing for those concerned.-^ Since the administration 
 of the law is vested in the Board of Health, its purpose is 
 plainly to protect the health of the community rather than 
 to benefit the workers, but, nevertheless, improved sur- 
 roundings cannot but accrue to the advantage of the em- 
 ployees. In so far, however, as the Board of Health con- 
 siders this law a pure health measure, its orders will be 
 and in fact have been much less in behalf of the laborers 
 than if the administration had been vested in the labor 
 department. 
 
 The specific provisions for the sanitary norms to be ap- 
 plied to the various food factories are almost ideal in their 
 nature.2^ It is first enacted that all of the rooms, furniture 
 and implements used in the preparation of food products 
 shall be kept in " a clean and sanitary condition," unclean 
 and unsanitary meaning the lack of protection of the food 
 itself against flies, filth, etc., the failure to remove all dirt 
 and waste product, and the failure to keep the persons of 
 the employees clean. It might have been provided that the 
 side walls and ceilings should be regularly lime-washed, but 
 in the absence of this stipulation it is to be expected that 
 the Board of Health will issue orders to fill the gap. It is 
 further enacted that "every . . . place occupied . . . for 
 
 23 Laws 1914, Ch. 678. 
 
 2* Ibid., Sec. I. 
 
 25 Ibid., Sec. 7. 
 
 2« Ibid., Sec. 3, Subsecs. a-f.
 
 90 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [236 
 
 the preparation, etc., of food shall have convenient toilet or 
 toilet rooms which shall be kept separate from the rooms 
 where the process of production, etc., is conducted, and all 
 parts of such toilet rooms shall be kept clean." Moreover, 
 the workers are forbidden to sleep in the workroom of a 
 bakeshop, etc., or in the kitchen or dining- room of a hotel, 
 restaurant or boarding house ; and the employer is forbid- 
 den to employ any worker affected with a communicable 
 disease unless he can produce a certificate from the Board 
 of Health permitting him to be employed in such a place. 
 Finally, washrooms are ordered to be constructed in these 
 factories. Further stipulations are laid down for canneries 
 in the State, but these are largely technical and do not add 
 much to the general provisions. 
 
 There is only one serious omission from this law : cellar 
 bakeries are not prohibited. It is obvious that " a cellar is 
 unfit both for the manufacture of food stuffs and for the 
 habitation of workers. There can be no natural light under 
 the most favorable conditions in a cellar. They are also 
 very difficult places to ventilate unless a mechanical system 
 is installed, which is out of the question in the ordinary 
 small bakery. . . . They cannot be kept as clean as other 
 parts of the house, for they are semi-dark, and contain most 
 of the plumbing pipes and fixtures. They are also the nat- 
 ural habitation of insects and rodents."" Although it is 
 true that conditions in Baltimore bakeries are not nearly so 
 bad as they are in New York and, in fact, it has been said 
 that there are no cellar bakeries in this city,^^ the absence 
 of the evil, as has been contended in another connection, 
 constitutes no real argument against sound prophylactic 
 legislation. 
 
 The Tenement Law. — In 1914, also, Maryland obtained 
 perhaps as efficient a homework or tenement law as is pos- 
 
 27 New York Factory Investigation Committee Report, Senate 
 Documents of New York, 1913, vol. 13, no. 36, pt. I, p. 222. 
 
 28 Dr. Caspari of the State Board of Health, who has charge of 
 the administration of this act is the authority for this statement.
 
 [237 THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 9 1 
 
 sible.^^ A tenement inspection law is practically always 
 inadequate because of the impossibility of proper inspection 
 even with the largest corps of well-trained inspectors. A 
 sufficient corps of inspectors may perhaps keep the tene- 
 ments free from filth and disease, but an absolutely efficient 
 administration of the child labor law or any other law affect- 
 ing the terms of labor is unattainable. Investigations in 
 New York have shown that children too young to be sent 
 to school were put to work helping the parent and that chil- 
 dren of school age were compelled to give help for such 
 unreasonable hours that their school work could hardly be 
 of any practical benefit.^" Moreover, it was argued by some 
 of the witnesses, that in view of the low wages paid tene- 
 ment workers it could not be denied that some manufactur- 
 ers were obtaining an unfair advantage in free rent and light 
 at the ultimate cost of the State in broken-down workers ; 
 but, pregnant as this contention may be in forcefully pre- 
 senting some of the evils of home work, it cannot be said 
 to be a potent argument for State interference. If the State 
 determines to regulate hours of labor, wages of labor and 
 child labor, and finds it impossible to do so while tenement 
 work-rooms exist, then, granting that it is within the power 
 of the State to undertake this regulation, the State would 
 have the right to prohibit home work. The health of the 
 community can be safeguarded by adequate or approxi- 
 mately adequate inspection of the conditions of employ- 
 ment, and that is the subject of this chapter. 
 
 The act provides for the registration of every factory, 
 workshop, or mercantile establishment employing five or 
 more people f^ and every room or part of a tenement houss 
 which is to be used for manufacture or repair work, except, 
 of course, the personal work of the occupants, must first 
 be licensed by the State Board of Labor and Statistics.^^ In 
 
 29 Laws 1914, Ch. 779. 
 
 30 Conducted by the Factory Investigating Committee. 
 
 31 Code 1914, Art. 27, Sec. ^4, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 406. 
 
 32 Ibid., Sec. 245.
 
 92 
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [238 
 
 New York the licensing of the whole tenement as a unit 
 has been found more efficient than the licensing of each 
 workshop separately since it interests the owner of the tene- 
 ment in the conditions of the separate workshops and makes 
 an additional person responsible for the sanitary conditions. 
 This is perhaps an improvement on the Maryland law, but 
 not of fundamental miportance, since, as it is, the manu- 
 facturer contracting out to home workers is also compelled 
 to see that the provisions cf the act are complied with in 
 the homes to which he sends his work.^^ These adminis- 
 trative features are the strong points of the law, and es- 
 pecially so when coupled with the minimum requirement of 
 one inspection every six months — a minimum, however, 
 much below comparative efficiency, but expedient for the 
 sake of economy. 
 
 Although below the most exacting standards, the sani- 
 tary provisions of the act, if conscientiously enforced, may 
 raise home work to a satisfactory sanitary level. The Board 
 of Labor and Statistics has powerful means in its hands to 
 enforce these provisions, for much is left to its discretion 
 in granting the licenses and it has power to revoke them 
 upon the slightest infringement of the conditions of their 
 grant.^* The board may refuse the license if the place can- 
 not show a clean health record. If the health record be 
 clean, then an inspection of the place is necessary; and, if 
 the board through its inspectors "ascertain that such' room 
 or apartment is free from . . . communicable disease and 
 is in proper sanitary condition, it shall grant a license " for 
 the place to be used by members of the family only, and 
 that only to the number of one worker to every five hun- 
 dred cubic feet of air space.^^ Though the New York com- 
 mission recommended more stringent sanitary regulations 
 than these, Massachusetts has practically the same provi- 
 sions as has Maryland. While not ideal, therefore, the 
 Maryland provisions at least may be said to be adequate. 
 
 8* Ibid., Sec. 247. 
 a* Ibid., Sec. 248. 
 '5 Ibid., Sec. 245.
 
 239] THE CONDITIONS OF EMPLOYMENT 93 
 
 In actual operation, however, the law is not so satisfac- 
 tory. The final determination of the sanitary condition has 
 been left in the hands of the local health department, for 
 the board has found it inexpedient to controvert the find- 
 ings of the health authorities as to health conditions. The 
 effect of this has been that practically no licenses have been 
 refused because of the presence of communicable diseases : 
 the health authorities rarely find any evidence of such dis- 
 eases or, if any is found, the conditions are soon corrected. 
 It is hardly within the scope of this study to indict the 
 health officials, but the performance of their part in the 
 enforcement of the law has been, to say the least, very 
 desultory.
 
 CHAPTER V 
 The Terms of Employment 
 
 Foreword. — The question of the extent to which the 
 State should interfere with the terms of employment is one 
 of the most acute of modern legislative problems. In gen- 
 eral, it may be said that as the State, on the one hand, is in 
 most cases warranted in regulating the conditions of em- 
 ployment, so, on the other hand, in most cases there must 
 be actual and positive cause for the extension of State activ- 
 ity to the control of the terms of employment. In general, 
 the problem of the hours and wages of employment should 
 be solved by the bargaining of the wage-earner and the em- 
 ployer. 
 
 The extent to which the State should interfere with the 
 terms of employment is, of course, one of the questions of 
 the science of legislation, and it should be solved according 
 to the norms and maxims of that science. But it is practi- 
 cally impossible for a student of American government to 
 consider legislative problems solely in the light of the prin- 
 ciples of legislation. If he could do so, his task would be 
 comparatively simple. An almost religious regard for the 
 law of the Constitution has so imbedded itself in the legal 
 thought of the United States that to think of framing an 
 enactment without scrupulous respect for its constitutional- 
 ity would be unpardonable sacrilege. It is this which ac- 
 counts for the obvious and deplorable lack of consistency 
 and scheme in the labor legislation of every State. The 
 grossest inconsistency is apparent in the enactments con- 
 cerning labor unions and the terms of the contract of em- 
 ployment. 
 
 In attempting to outline an ideal and consistent scheme 
 of legislation, I shall attempt to prove in a subsequent chap- 
 
 94
 
 241] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT 95 
 
 ter that legislation regulating the terms of employment is 
 only justified as a temporary expedient. Labor legislation, 
 as has been so often iterated, is a means of equalizing the 
 bargaining power of labor and capital, but the greatest 
 equalizer, it will be shown, is the union. Until the ideal of 
 complete unionization is attained, State interference with 
 the terms of employment is justified. The courts have up- 
 held legislation in respect to the hours and wages of em- 
 ployment of women and children, but have quite as unani- 
 mously overthrown similar legislation for unorganized 
 workingmen unless the occupation is especially danger- 
 ous. They have thus established a principle of American 
 legislation, but a principle which is unsound. It seems to 
 be based upon two fundamental conceptions. In the first 
 place, women and children because of their weaker nature 
 have all through the common law been considered just re- 
 cipients of the protection of the law. The courts have, 
 therefore, always rather welcomed^ legislation delimiting 
 the employment of women and children. Their antagonism 
 to legislation for adult males, however, is unjustified, for, 
 although the weakness of women and children does entitle 
 them to additional protection from the State against undue 
 influence and fraud, the unorganized male laborer is in as 
 unfair a position in making a wage contract with the aver- 
 age employer as the weakest woman. Mental strength has 
 little effect against a dominating force. In the second place, 
 the courts in upholding labor legislation of this kind put it 
 most often in the rubric of health laws. Of course, it is 
 true that the physical condition of women and children is 
 less resistant than that of men, and, moreover, it is easy to 
 argue that the welfare of the community is more strictly 
 connected with the health of women and children than with 
 that of men. But this is largely a matter of degree and 
 hardly the occasion for such a strict drawing of constitu- 
 tional lines. A needless inconsistency is the result. 
 
 1 1 think that I am justified in the use of this word in view of the 
 decision in Bosley v. McLoughlin, 236 U. S. 385,
 
 q6 the labor law of MARYLAND [242 
 
 If to this inconsistency is added the pressure of all kinds 
 of reform organizations for every conceivable limitation of 
 the terms of labor and the cheap politics displayed by can- 
 didates competing for the vote of the laboring class, the 
 possibilities of a shapeless system of labor legislation seem 
 of limitless magnitude. This shapelessness has been more 
 than achieved. Instead of the almost total absence of leg- 
 islation regulating hours and wages of labor which would 
 be the case under ideal conditions, the statutes of the aver- 
 age State are an enervating hodge-podge. Antiquated and 
 useless legislation is left on the books to the confusion of 
 the lawyer and student; conflicting laws are enacted with- 
 out taking the trouble to repeal the earlier laws ; criminal 
 laws without penalties are set forth as sops to some now 
 forgotten reform movement ; and high sounding laws with 
 fatal exceptions are in endless abundance. This is a con- 
 cise and exact description of the legislation of Maryland 
 in spite of some recent efforts of the legislators. There is 
 absolutely no unity or system present. It must not be un- 
 derstood, however, that Maryland is unique in this respect. 
 Except for those States, of which Wisconsin is the fore- 
 most example, which have practically repealed all their pre- 
 vious labor law and left to a commission the evolution of a 
 new system, every State of the Union is equally guilty. 
 Even New York, which has recently adopted almost an en- 
 tire new code of labor legislation has been remiss in failing 
 to repeal the earlier law. But for an estimate of the status 
 of the laborer in Maryland, some study of this phase of the 
 law is necessary. For the purposes of this chapter I have, 
 therefore, arranged the laws under three heads : first, those 
 prohibiting the employment of certain classes in specified 
 occupations; second, those regulating the hours of labor; 
 and, third, those regulating the wages of labor. 
 
 Prohibitions of Employment.— The absolute prohibitions 
 contained in the Maryland labor law with the two excep- 
 tions referring to the employment of women as barmaids'* 
 
 2 Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art. 13, Sees. 195-196.
 
 243] "^^^ TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT 97 
 
 and as waitresses in places of amusement^ are all confined 
 to child labor. The laws forbidding absolutely the use of 
 dangerous materials or methods in any occupation have ob- 
 tained no foothold in this State. Indeed, there are few 
 laws of this kind in the country, only one, the federal pro- 
 hibitive tax on the phosphorous matchmaking industry, 
 being a typical example. An anti-homework law might be 
 desirable. This type of legislation is much more effective 
 than the regulatory laws described in the last chapter, to 
 which they are closely related, but the American tendency 
 is towards regulation rather than absolute prohibition. 
 
 The usual prohibitions to be found in any State, then, 
 refer to child labor ; the education of the child and the pro- 
 tection of the young person, as he is technically called, being 
 the ends of the law. Thus in Maryland no minor under 
 twenty-one years of age is permitted to work in or in con- 
 nection with any place where spirituous liquors are sold.* 
 It seems exceedingly doubtful whether this provision is 
 strictly enforced for the difficulties of administration are 
 obvious. Prohibition reform would, of course, be more effi- 
 cient; and even putting the enforcement in the hands of the 
 Liquor License Board might aid in increasing the efTective- 
 ness of the law. 
 
 Children under the age of eighteen years, as in most 
 other industrial States, are forbidden to work in or about 
 " blast furnaces, docks or wharves ; or in the outside erec- 
 tion and repair of electric wires ; in the running or man- 
 agement of elevators, lifts or hoisting machines or dyna- 
 mos ; in oiling or cleaning machinery in motion ; ... at 
 switch tending, gate tending, track repairing or as brake- 
 men, firemen, engineers, etc., upon railroads ; ... or in or 
 about establishments, where . . . high or dangerous explo- 
 sives are manufactured, compounded or stored . . ." or in 
 
 3 Code 1914, Art. 27, Sees. 44:^-443. 
 
 *Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 22 (to be Art. 100 of Code); Code 
 191 1, Art. 56, Sec. 98.
 
 ^8 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [244 
 
 Other like occupations wherein their immaturity would ren- 
 der them inefficient.^ 
 
 Children under sixteen years of age are rigidly circum- 
 scribed in their employment. They are forbidden to be 
 employed around dangerous machines as circular or band 
 saws, picker machines or machines used in picking wool, 
 cotton or any other material, job or cylinder printing 
 presses operated by machinery, stamping machines and 
 numerous others specified at great length. They are not 
 permitted to work upon any steam, electric or hydraulic 
 railway or on any machinery operated by power other than 
 hand or foot power, or upon any vessel or boat engaged in 
 navigation or commerce. Occupations wherein dangerous 
 or poisonous acids are used are closed to them, as is min- 
 ing and the allied occupation of tunneling. They are for- 
 bidden to perform in any concert hall or playhouse in con- 
 nection with any professional theatrical performance, ex- 
 hibition or show.^ 
 
 There is also a prohibition of the employment of females 
 under sixteen where such employment compels them to re- 
 main constantly standing.'^ This is really more of a regu- 
 lation of the conditions than of the terms of employment ; 
 and, though somewhat vague, it is fundamentally an exem- 
 plary piece of legislation in which Maryland seems to have 
 established a precedence. Moreover, no child under six- 
 teen can be employed in any occupation until he has ob- 
 tained a permit from the Bureau of Statistics in Baltimore 
 City or from the superintendent of schools in a county. 
 These employment permits or certificates are of two classes, 
 general and vacation employment certificates, and are is- 
 sued only on the conditions of a satisfactory school record, 
 of a favorable report from a competent physician, and evi- 
 dence that the child is of legal age to work in the desired 
 
 "Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 21. 
 
 « Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sees. 7S, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 222, 
 and see Code 1914, Art. 27, Sec. 346. 
 ^ Laws 1916, Ch. 222, Sec. 23.
 
 245] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT 99 
 
 occupation.^ The granting of these certificates is regulated 
 moreover by stringent administrative provisions. Similar 
 to these certificates, but with the necessary differences, are 
 the badges granted to boys between the ages of twelve and 
 sixteen to sell papers and periodicals on the street during 
 daylight.^ 
 
 Subject to these stipulations and exceptions, it is legal in 
 Maryland to employ children above the age of fourteen. 
 Children under fourteen are forbidden to be employed " in, 
 about or in connection with any mill, factory, mechanical 
 establishment, tenement house, . . . office building, . . . 
 public stable, garage or in any mercantile establishment 
 . . . , place of amusement, club, etc.," in short, in most 
 occupations. ^° The fourteen year age limit is also estab- 
 lished to a certain degree by prohibiting the employment 
 under that age during school hours.^^ There are, however, 
 in the Maryland law two provisions allowing the employ- 
 ment outside of school hours of children above the age of 
 twelve in " canning or packing establishments,"^^ and of 
 males above the age of twelve in the sale of periodicals and 
 newspapers on the streets. Boys above ten may with a 
 permit distribute papers on a regular route between the 
 hours of 3 130 and 5 :oo p.m.^^ If the twelve year mini- 
 mum is enforced in canneries and allied occupations, Mary- 
 land children are better protected than those in most other 
 canning States, in New York, at least, it having been found 
 practically impossible to enforce a fourteen year minimum.^* 
 
 On the whole, this rubric of the Maryland labor law at- 
 tains as high a standard as that set anywhere in the coun- 
 try. The Child Labor Law is a recent enactment and seems 
 
 8 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 9 ff. 
 
 8 Ibid., Sees. 27-33. 
 
 ^0 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 4, as amended by Acts 1916, Sec. 222. 
 
 ^1 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 6; Laws 1912, Ch. 173. 
 
 12 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 5. 
 
 ^3 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sec. 26, as finally amended by Laws 1916, 
 Ch. 222. 
 
 ^* See Annual Report of Commissioner of Labor, New York, 1914, 
 P- 135.
 
 lOO THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [246 
 
 to have been drafted in a scientific and careful manner, fol- 
 lowing rather closely the laws of New York and Massachu- 
 setts, which mark a high plane in the conservative reform 
 law of this country. There is, however, one prohibition 
 omitted in the Maryland labor law which experts have come 
 to consider absolutely necessary. Most European countries 
 and four American States, Connecticut, Massachusetts, 
 New York and Vermont, forbid the employment of women 
 for certain periods before and after childbirth. There is no 
 doubt of the constitutionality of such a law, for it has been 
 amply demonstrated that the community suffers from the 
 high rate of mortality and morbidity of babies who fail to 
 receive sufficient care from their mothers. Such a law, how- 
 ever, would involve a considerable step towards communism, 
 especially as the perfected plan would call for some kind 
 of aid from the State during the period of enforced rest.^^ 
 
 Hours. — The regulation of the hours of labor has caused 
 the legislators of the last quarter of a century the greatest 
 difficulty. The exact limit of their power has not been 
 clearly defined, and they can never be sure that their 
 enactments compelled by the clamors of reformers, eco- 
 nomic and political, will be upheld by the courts. It is in 
 fact within this rubric of the labor law that the attempt is 
 sometimes made to limit the police power of the State. 
 Somewhere a law ceases to be an exercise of the police 
 power and becomes a taking of property without due proc- 
 ess of law. The doctrine of reasonableness has been formu- 
 lated by the courts, but this doctrine hardly gives any true 
 clue to the problem. It is best to say that there is much 
 hopeless conflict between the courts and that in the end each 
 law must be considered on its own merits. 
 
 The economic argument for restricting the hours of labor 
 has been so often iterated and reiterated that it has become 
 
 *5 The Italian plan raises the fund for the care of the indigent 
 mothers by taxing each woman of child-bearing age employed in any 
 industry thirteen cents a month, each employer seven cents per 
 month per woman of that age employed by him, and by an addi- 
 tional seven cents per woman contributed by the state.
 
 247] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT lOI 
 
 shopworn ; and it will not be worth while to set it forth at 
 length. The arguments of the economists may well be ac- 
 cepted at their face value, but must then be considered from 
 the viewpoint of legislation. The economic argument runs 
 something like this: Long hours are physically injurious. 
 Long hours stultify the intellectual growth of the individual 
 because of lack of time for self-enlightenment. Long hours 
 lead to immorality and excess in recreation. Long hours 
 tend to lessen the influence of family life and ultimately to 
 destroy it. The shortening of hours more than pays for 
 itself in increased efficiency.^® And then, having heaped up 
 facts, the economist will emphasize one of them, the physi- 
 cal deterioration or the intellectual stultification, depending 
 on whether the law in question bears upon women or chil- 
 dren. The courts accept this reasoning and uphold hours- 
 of-labor laws for women and children. When a law limit- 
 ing the hours of labor of men is presented to them, the 
 courts have generally refused to sanction it, though the 
 economic argument for it is precisely the same. There is 
 here an inconsistency due to the lack of a complete scheme 
 or philosophy of labor legislation. 
 
 The limitations on the hours of labor of children in Mary- 
 land were not of a very high standard until 1916. Prior to 
 that there was, except for the two provisions aimed at keep- 
 ing messengers and newsboys off the streets at night," only 
 a general prohibition that no child under sixteen should 
 labor more than ten hours a day in any manufacturing busi- 
 ness in the State or in any mercantile establishment in Bal- 
 timore.^^ Now there is a strict prohibition of labor of chil- 
 dren under sixteen in enumerated occupations, including 
 practically all except canning and domestic labor, for more 
 than six days in any one week, or more than forty-eight 
 
 ^* For a typical example, see the brief prepared by Mr. Louis 
 Brandeis for the Consumers' League in Muller v. Oregon, 208 
 U. S. 412. 
 
 ^^ Laws 1912, Ch. 731, Sees. 24-32, and see also Code 191 1, Art. 
 23, Sec. 375. 
 
 18 Code 1914, Art. 27, Sec. 239; Laws 1892, Ch. 443.
 
 102 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [248 
 
 hours during that time, or more than eight hours in any one 
 day, or between the hours of seven in the evening and seven 
 in the morning. Moreover, the mere "presence of such 
 child in any estabHshment shall be prima facie evidence of 
 its employment."^" This is an almost ideal law, the excep- 
 tion of canning and domestic labor being necessitated by 
 expediency. The prohibition of night work and the final 
 administrative provision merit special attention. Minors 
 above sixteen are not specially legislated for in Maryland 
 and are included in the legislation for adults. 
 
 The maximum legal extent of employment for women in 
 Maryland is ten hours in any one day and sixty hours in a 
 week.-" This law was enacted in 1912 after a bitter strug- 
 gle, but, as it stands now on our statute book, Maryland 
 ranks about on the level with most other States of the coun- 
 try in this respect. There are, however, two exceptions in 
 the Maryland act which are interesting. The first exception 
 exempts from the operation of the law females employed 
 in the canning or preserving or preparation for canning or 
 preserving of perishable fruits and vegetables. Although 
 this exception has been bitterly assailed by the reform 
 forces and although it is illogical and perhaps unsocial, yet 
 it seems perfectly justified by expediency. New York, 
 which has enacted a ten-hour law applying to canneries, 
 has found it practically impossible to enforce it, though the 
 labor commissioner has hopes of slow education up to the 
 standard. 2^ Some sort of limitation of hours in canneries 
 is needed — perhaps a graduated scale over several years 
 would be feasible — but no law is better than an unenforced 
 and unenforcible law. The other exception allows twelve 
 hours' work on Saturdays and six days preceding Christ- 
 mas in retail mercantile establishments outside the City of 
 Baltimore, provided that there are two periods of rest on 
 
 i» Laws 1916, Ch. 222, Sec. 22A. 
 
 20 Laws 1912, Ch. 79, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 147. 
 
 bee Report of New York Commissioner of Labor for 1914,
 
 249] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT IO3 
 
 those days and provided also that the women in these estab- 
 Hshments work no more than nine hours a day during the 
 remainder of the year. Here again the exception is not 
 logically sound, but is dictated by administrative expedi- 
 ency. New York has a similar exception. 
 
 There is no prohibition of night work for women, that 
 is, no hours between which women are not allowed to labor ; 
 only instead of ten hours per day being the legal limit a 
 shorter day of eight hours is stipulated. This is a serious 
 omission. Night work practically deprives women of any 
 but the most meager period of rest on account of the insist- 
 ence of household duties during the day when the worker 
 is supposed to be sleeping. Moreover, night work makes 
 the complete and efficient enforcement of the legal day al- 
 most impossible, for unless certain opening and closing 
 hours are fixed,' an inspector cannot unearth violations ex- 
 cept by spending all his time in one factory checking up the 
 various women as they come in and leave. Both New York 
 and Massachusetts prohibit night work for women. 
 
 The limitations put upon the hours of labor of men are 
 more in the nature of norms than absolute regulations. 
 This is what would be expected. Thus eight hours is the 
 legal day for employees of the City of Baltimore and for 
 employees of contractors engaged in public work.^^ There 
 is an exception allowing overtime for the protection of life 
 and property, an exception which can easily be stretched to 
 cover ordinary overtime. Again, there is the provision that 
 ten hours shall be the legal day in cotton and woolen manu- 
 factories^^ and in mines in Alleghany and Garrett counties,^* 
 but any adult male may contract to work longer. However, 
 for public safety, street car employees^-'^ and train dispatch- 
 ers on a railroad employing the block system^*' are limited 
 to twelve and eight hours a day, respectively. These laws 
 
 22 Laws 1910, Ch. 94. See also Laws 1916, Ch. 134. 
 
 23 Code 191 1, Art. 100, Sees. 1-2. 
 
 24 Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art. 12, Sec. 165; Art. I, Sec. 194. 
 
 25 Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sees. 793-5. 
 2«Code 1911, Art. 23, Sec. 323.
 
 104 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [25O 
 
 are not important in a general estimate of labor conditions. 
 The public-works law does give some evidence of the 
 strength of labor as a political force and the ineffective 
 laws display a further attempt of the legislature, bootless 
 this time, to curry favor with the workingmen, but neither 
 are particularly instructive examples of State activity. 
 
 Wages. — When we come to consider the third kind of 
 legislation regulating the terms of employment, laws with 
 regard to the wages of labor, an entirely new field is opened 
 to the investigator. There are, of course, the enactments 
 protecting the laborer against the fraud and delay of the 
 employer, but what is most interesting to the student of leg- 
 islation is the recent tendency of States to set minimum 
 wages for various classes of workers. This is a reversion 
 to the Middle Ages practice of setting a " fair and just " 
 wage with the significant substitution of a legal minimum 
 for a legally absolute wage. The distinction certainly is 
 significant, but both the "fair and just" and the minimum 
 wage are enactments of a very paternalistic government. 
 
 Recognizing " that not only hours and working conditions 
 where there is inequality of bargaining, properly concern the 
 state, but that the question of wages also has a direct con- 
 nection with the welfare of the worker, and therefore of the 
 public," a score of states, American and foreign, have en- 
 acted minimum wage laws. "Wages," it is further stated 
 by this advocate of these laws, " have a decided bearing on 
 the health of the employees. The workers who have suffi- 
 cient nourishing food and who live under healthful condi- 
 tions are more resistant to the evil effects of working con- 
 ditions. Living conditions are dependent to a very large 
 extent upon working conditions, and a betterment of hours 
 and wages means a betterment of the mode of living and 
 therefore of the efficiency of the worker."" The argument 
 is incontestable if health is the standard according to which 
 the state should guarantee every worker a "living wage," 
 
 " Report of Industrial Commission of Wisconsin for Two Years 
 Endmg June 30, 1914, p. 58.
 
 251] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT IO5 
 
 the protests of the capitalists to the contrary notwithstand- 
 ing; but if the goal of state regulation is to establish equal- 
 ity of bargaining power, if the aim of state interference is 
 to remedy causes, not symptoms, then minimum wage leg- 
 islation seems beyond the limits of state activity, although 
 perhaps a useful temporary expedient. Maryland has no 
 minimum wage law, and, according to the doctrines which 
 are advocated in this study, her stand is correct. 
 
 All of the laws, of course, apply only to females and 
 minors, for the same reasons that all other laws relating to 
 the terms of employment are restricted to them. Most of 
 the enactments are general in their wording, leaving to ad- 
 ministrative boards the interpretation of the general terms. 
 " Every wage paid or agreed to be paid by an employer to 
 any female or minor employee . . . shall be not less than 
 a living wage " except that incompetents may be granted 
 licenses to work at lower rates, says the Wisconsin law ; 
 and a " ' living wage ' shall mean compensation . . . suffi- 
 cient to enable the employee ... to maintain himself or 
 herself " in " reasonable comfort, reasonable well-being, 
 decency and moral well-being."^^ To administer these laws 
 steps are taken very similar to those described in the last 
 chapter in connection with the commission form of labor 
 legislation. Some kind of commission is always given the 
 administration of the law. If the commission has any rea- 
 son to believe that the wages paid females or minors in any 
 industry or trade are unreasonably low or if any individ- 
 ual or organization complains to the commission that such 
 conditions exist, the commission will begin an investigation 
 into the wage conditions in that industry. This preliminary 
 investigation is usually ex parte and is in the nature of an 
 inquest by the grand jury. If the commission decides that 
 there is reason to believe that there is some truth in these 
 suspicions, it appoints a board composed of employees and 
 employers with sometimes a representative of the public to 
 
 28 Wisconsin Acts 1913, Ch. 712, Sec. 1729, s-i, (4) and (5) ; 2, 7,
 
 I06 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [252 
 
 investigate thoroughly and determine on a Hving wage. 
 This board usually has power to summon and pay witnesses 
 and every one interested may appear. The minimum de- 
 cided upon, either per day, per week or by the piece, ac- 
 cording to the industry, is then reported back to the govern- 
 ment commission, before whom may appear any complain- 
 ants who are aggrieved at the board's findings. When the 
 legal minimum is finally proclaimed, all employers in that 
 industry must conform to the rulings of the commission. 
 In some States, however, for example, Massachusetts,^^ the 
 penalty for disobedience is merely uncomfortable publicity. 
 If the minimum wage is really well founded such a sanc- 
 tion is sufficient. 
 
 It is obvious that under a minimum wage law the em- 
 ployer is not obliged to pay for what he does not receive, 
 he must only pay a little more than he has been accustomed 
 to pay. He is not obliged to pay a piece-worker so much 
 per week no matter how much she may loaf during the 
 week. He is not obliged to pay the unskilled as much as 
 the skilled. The delinquent is allowed to work for less than 
 the competent and children for less than adults. Most in- 
 dustries will not be affected by the legal minimum — wages 
 there are above it — and those affected are expected to get 
 more work for the higher wages through the increased ef- 
 ficiency of the workers. The minimum wage laws have 
 been evolved to a high degree of efficiency in their details. 
 Arguments against them must attack the fundamentals, not 
 the superstructure. 
 
 Of an entirely different nature from the minimum wage 
 laws are those enactments regulating the wage agreements 
 of adult men ; for though these laws are general and apply 
 to all workers, it is because they include men that new leg- 
 islative and constitutional principles are involved. This 
 legislation is justified on the ground that it is aimed pri- 
 marily at fraud. The employer on account of his position 
 
 29 Massachusetts Acts 1912, Ch. 706, as amended by Acts 1914, 
 Cn. 300.
 
 253] THE TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT 10/ 
 
 as trustee for the earned but unpaid wages of his employ- 
 ees is in such a superior position that he is able, if he wishes, 
 to exercise the most fraudulent compulsion upon the work- 
 ers. It is at this evil that this last class of laws affecting 
 the terms of labor is aimed. An example, though a rather 
 extreme example, of the protection afforded by the State 
 is the law forbidding railroad companies doing business 
 within the State to withhold any part of the wages of its 
 employees for the benefit of any relief association or the 
 members thereof.^*' Most of the laws, however, are aimed 
 at the insidious truck system, as it is called, which has now 
 fortunately become practically extinct in the eastern sections 
 of the country. ^^ 
 
 The truck system has largely depended upon the fact 
 that nature is so perverse as to establish her most necessary 
 metallic resources in out-of-the-way places. Mining com- 
 munities have always been on the economic frontier of civ- 
 ilization. A not unusual occurrence is the springing up of 
 a full-sized town out of an uncultivated waste. In these 
 cases the mining company is generally the owner of the 
 town, the land, the homes and the public buildings. If not 
 thus far centralized, at least the source of the food supply 
 is in the hands of the mining company. At first the com- 
 pany is performing a real economic service in establishing 
 the company store, and it is a real benefit to the workers 
 to have a steady source from which to purchase their neces- 
 sities instead of having to rely on the possibility of an itin- 
 erant huckster. This is the good side of the truck system ; 
 and, perhaps, in the right hands, the company store might 
 remain a benefit to the laborers, although the monopolistic 
 weapons of the shop are of a really dangerous nature. But 
 
 30 Code 191 1, Art. 23, Sec. 315. 
 
 31 Most of the information about the truck system has been taken 
 from the Report of the Commissioners Appointed to Inquire into 
 the Truck System, 1871. The general features of the system are so 
 constant that, it is believed, nothing has been lost by using an Eng- 
 lish instead of an American source, especially since the English 
 source is generally available and compact.
 
 I08 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [254 
 
 the truck system is usually attended by much more sinister 
 forces. 
 
 The truck system is usually sustained by the maintain- 
 ance of long intervals between pay days, although in Scot- 
 land it was found to exist where the interval was only two 
 weeks. Now the miners as a class earn just about the mar- 
 ginal subsistence wages and have very little chance to be 
 provident. If the employee does not begin his employment 
 under the necessity of obtaining credit, he has many chances 
 of acquiring this unenviable position. The company store 
 avails itself of this opportunity in two ways. Sometimes 
 it merely extends credit to the laborer, establishing a sort 
 of lien on his accruing wages and collecting this lien by a 
 system of bookkeeping in the company's office or by setting 
 up a collection office so close to the paymaster's window 
 that escape from its clutches is impossible. Its credits are 
 therefore much safer than those of any chance competitor. 
 Sometimes, where there exists the system of advances 
 from the company's coffers on the men's wages, the store 
 profits by a kind of moral compulsion to spend this volun- 
 tary advance in the company store, although more tangible 
 constraint is not unknown: "black lists are often kept of 
 slopers [those who do not spend the advances in the com- 
 pany store] ; threats of dismissal were repeatedly proved; 
 and cases of actual dismissal . . . are not rare."^^ More- 
 over, even the most provident among the employees seem 
 to think it to their advantage to deal at least to some extent 
 at the company store: it is a natural impression for the 
 worker to think that his job is more secure if he caters to 
 his employer. The dominance which the employer can 
 secure over the laborer is evident, the double profits which 
 he can reap are enormous. And, moreover, the laborer 
 rarely gets fair play, for monopoly and the credit features 
 of a company store allow the owner to advance prices to a 
 
 "Report of the Commissioners Appointed to Inquire into the 
 Truck System, 1871, p. xvi.
 
 255] "^"^ TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT IO9 
 
 considerable extent. The truck system, indeed, seems to 
 call most urgently for state regulation.'^ 
 
 In legislating upon this subject Maryland has had a check- 
 ered experience. The coal fields in the two western coun- 
 ties of the State furnished an ideal opportunity for the 
 growth of the company store ; and, though the conditions 
 and the acts passed to meet those conditions are not of prac- 
 tical importance to-day, yet because of the number of these 
 laws and because of the decisions based upon them it has 
 been thought worth while to spend enough time on them at 
 least to outline them. As far back as 1868 the legislature 
 decreed that " no railroad or mining corporation . . . shall 
 own, conduct or carry on any store, or have any interest in 
 any store."^* This law does not seem to have been very 
 effective, for two other laws, this time local in their effect, 
 were later enacted. By these every corporation engaged in 
 mining or manufacturing or operating a railroad in Alle- 
 ghany and Garrett counties was compelled to pay the wages 
 of its employees in legal tender of the United States f^ and, 
 in Alleghany County, it is further provided that " no such 
 corporation . . . shall issue any script or metallic or paper 
 checks in payment of the sums due such employees, nor 
 shall such employees make any contract with their employ- 
 ers by which such employees shall be compelled to purchase 
 their supplies, merchandise or goods from any private or 
 company stores owned and operated by said employers ; nor 
 shall . . . [the employers] exercise any influence whatever 
 ... to compel their employees to deal with any particular 
 merchant or storekeepers."^* 
 
 This last amendment makes this law about as inclusive 
 and adequate as it is possible to make a law regulating such 
 a multiform evil. It is the direct outgrowth of a Maryland 
 
 8^ A regulation and prohibition of the truck system has been held 
 constitutional in Knoxville Iron Co. v. Harbison, 183 U. S. 13. 
 3* Laws 1868, Ch. 471, Sec. 217; Code 1911, Art. 23, Sec. 311. 
 
 35 Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art. 1, Sec. 185; Laws 1892, 
 Ch. 445. 
 
 36 Amendment added by Laws 1900, Ch. 453.
 
 no THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [256 
 
 case" construing an allied act and of a Supreme Court 
 decision.^^ To understand this law a little history must be 
 indulged in. The local law for Alleghany County as first 
 passed was declared constitutional as a justified exercise of 
 the police power of the State in Shaffer v. Union Mining 
 Co. f^ but it was held in this case that an assignment of 
 wages to merchants who were tenants of the mining com- 
 pany was not included within the prohibition of the act. 
 This decision much weakened the law, for the truck sys- 
 tem has been found just as noxious when the store is run 
 by tenants of the company as when run by the company 
 itself. The law in fact proved inadequate and there was 
 passed a bill rendering it imlawful for any officer or direc- 
 tor of a mining or railroad corporation to have any interest 
 in any general store in Alleghany County.*" This act was 
 aimed at what has recently become well known as interlock- 
 ing directorates, but it was almost immediately declared 
 unconstitutional as interfering with the equal protection of 
 the laws.*^ " Though it was perfectly competent," say the 
 court, " for the legislature to prevent railroad and mining 
 corporations from engaging in the business of bartering or 
 selling goods . . . ; yet it was not within the power of the 
 General Assembly to deny to particular individuals who 
 happened to be officers of those corporations, and merely 
 because they were such officers the right which every other 
 citizen of the country . . . possessed to sell goods." And 
 further, " the owners of a mine have no other control over 
 the employee * than that which may result from employing 
 him, etc. ; and every other employer of labor has precisely 
 the same control over those who obtain or wish to obtain 
 employment with him.' "*2 In this case the court clearly 
 refused to take judicial cognizance of the truck system and 
 
 3^ Luman v. Kitchens, 90 Md. 14; 46 L. R. A. 393. 
 
 38 Knoxville Iron Co. v. Harbison : see above. 
 
 »^ 55 Md. 74. 
 
 *o Laws 1898, Ch. 493. 
 
 *^ Luman v. Hitchens ; see above. 
 
 *2 Quoting from Frorer v. People, 141 111. 171 ; 16 L. R. A. 492.
 
 257] ^^^ TERMS OF EMPLOYMENT III 
 
 especially of the truck system as it flourished in Alleghany 
 County, Maryland. The case was decided on purely legal 
 grounds ; and, being one of those cases in which constitu- 
 tionality was peculiarly a question of fact, it is submitted 
 that the court was in error. This case, however, is not so 
 reactionary and destructive as a case which followed it, that 
 of Luman v. Hitchens. This case led to the amendment of 
 the earlier law and the amendment, as has been intimated, 
 is really more efficient than the unconstitutional act. 
 
 Thus far only those laws directly attacking the truck 
 system have been considered ; but since the truck system 
 depends for its maintenance upon long intervals between 
 pay days, acts regulating the time of pay will be practically 
 as efficacious as the out-and-out company store laws. 
 Maryland has three such acts on her statute book, though 
 it is probable that only one is really constitutional. This is 
 a law contained in the corporation article of the code de- 
 creeing that " every association or corporation doing busi- 
 ness in the State of Maryland employing wage earners . . . 
 in the business of mining, manufacturing, operating a steam 
 or electric railroad, street railway, telegraph, telephone or 
 express company shall make payments in lawful money of 
 the United States semi-monthly to said employees."*^ This 
 law seems to include all businesses mentioned in the previ- 
 ous law pertaining to corporations engaged in mining and 
 shipping coal in Alleghany County,** so that this earlier law 
 is entirely superseded. A later act was passed, however, 
 applying the same terms to " all corporations and individual 
 mine-owners . . . engaged in mining coal or fire clay in 
 Garrett County."" This addition of " individual mine- 
 owners " was the result of the decision of Luman v. 
 Hitchens,*^ which was interpreted as based on the singling 
 out of corporations for stricter regulations. In State v. 
 Potomac Coal Company,*^ however, the court on the ground 
 
 "Code 1911, Art. 23, Sec. 123. 
 "Laws 1896, Ch. 133. 
 *^ Laws 1910, Ch. 211. 
 *^ Cited above. 
 *'ii6 Md. 380.
 
 112 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [258 
 
 of the earlier case declared the later act unconstitutional as 
 a violation of the "equal protection of the laws" clause 
 because the law was confined to the mining industry in the 
 one county. The court again based its decision on purely 
 legal grounds and seems to have narrowed the police power 
 to an unreasonable extent. Though the court's argument 
 seems discouragingly restrictive, and not specifically based 
 on facts, the facts do nevertheless to a great degree uphold 
 it, for the truck system in 191 1 was not nearly so insidious 
 as it was when the court refused to recognize it in 1899. It 
 is, however, lucky that the adverse decision of the court 
 came after the truck system had virtually disappeared, for 
 it would have been practically impossible to legislate against 
 it if the industries in which it was prevalent could not have 
 been reached by special legislation. 
 
 Any discussion of state regulation of the terms of em- 
 ployment should include at least a mention of the tendency 
 towards state aided pensions for sickness, old age, unem- 
 ployment and the like. This movement has attained great 
 prominence in many foreign countries, and recently Great 
 Britain has followed the lead of the more radical Domin- 
 ions. One such scheme of state aid in the unemployment 
 insurance of labor unions will be discussed in the last chap- 
 ter as a means whereby the state might obtain control of 
 union affairs. As such, as a governmental device, these 
 pensions are perhaps justified; but, as purely social legisla- 
 tion, they are quite beyond the police power of the state 
 as it is conceived in this study, whether we define the police 
 power from a legal or a legislative point of view.
 
 CHAPTER VI 
 Some Miscellaneous Laws 
 
 There will be considered in this chapter a number of laws 
 which are only incidentally labor laws, but which play an 
 important part in the legal and social welfare of Maryland. 
 These will be treated under four heads : ( i ) license laws ; 
 (2) laws governing attachments and liens for wages — laws 
 of legal practice and procedure primarily; (3) child wel- 
 fare laws; and (4) State employment laws. 
 
 Licenses. — There is in Maryland the beginning of a li- 
 cense system. In so far as it is intended for a comprehen- 
 sive system of licensing occupations in order to make the 
 State a sponsor for the proficiency of its working people, 
 the Maryland license laws are really only a beginning, but 
 compared with the license laws of other States, they seem 
 fairly extensive. Licenses are required of barbers, plumb- 
 ers and chauffeurs throughout the State, and of electricians, 
 horseshoers, moving picture operators, stationary engineers 
 and master stevedores in Baltimore City. Practically the 
 only important occupation licensed in other States which is 
 not licensed in Maryland is mining; but withal the Mary- 
 land miners are an efficient and intelligent class. 
 
 Licenses are required by the State for two reasons. 
 Some license laws, as, for instance, those controlling ped- 
 dlers and real estate dealers, are enacted purely for revenue 
 purposes. They indirectly serve as police measures, but 
 their primary purpose is to secure revenue.^ The other 
 class of license laws, beginning with those regulating the 
 practice of medicine and law and extending down to horse- 
 shoers, are enacted primarily as police measures to protect 
 the public from quacks and inefficient workmen. To this 
 
 1 See Coates v. Locust Point Co., 102 Md. 297. 
 8 113
 
 114 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [260 
 
 class belong all the laws affecting the laborer except per- 
 haps the master stevedore law,^ which as it now stands in 
 its emasculated form is hard to understand. As first en- 
 acted, it required both a license fee and a bond to secure 
 the payment of wages to the journeymen stevedores. The 
 Court of Appeals, however, declared the bonding provision 
 unconstitutional, but did not question the licensing section ;' 
 yet it is hard to see why, if the State can protect those work- 
 ers who are hired by a master stevedore against fraud and 
 insolvency by a twenty-five dollar license fee, it cannot more 
 adequately protect them by a thousand dollar bond. The 
 regard of the courts for the historical activities of the State 
 and their aversion towards new modes of State activity is 
 perhaps the only explanation. 
 
 The other laws,* if considered together, suggest an inter- 
 esting hypothesis. Except for the chauffeurs, an exception 
 which is easily explained, all the occupations licensed in 
 Maryland are organized into substantial unions. Is the 
 State, perhaps unconsciously, rendering a most valuable aid 
 to the organizing of these occupations? That the unions 
 are strongly in favor of these laws and that they put forth 
 every effort of which they are capable to secure them is an 
 unconcealed fact; that their efforts are of much avail and 
 that the results are beneficial is more debatable. That these 
 laws are of some use seems indisputable. A typical instance 
 is furnished by the operation of the laws of the Middle 
 Western States licensing miners. When a strike is the or- 
 der of the day, the men in the mines stop work and the mine 
 owners are unable to fill their places because of the lack of 
 licensed men outside the ranks of the strikers. This is true, 
 
 2 Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sec. 700A. 
 
 a Steeken y. State, 88 Md. 708. 
 
 *The various laws are codified as follows: Barbers, Code 191 1, 
 Art. 43, Sees. 209-222; Chauffers, Code 191 1, Art. 56, Sec. 139; Elec- 
 tricians, Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sec. 663, m-q; Horse-shoers, 
 Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sec. 515, a-f ; Moving Picture Opera- 
 tors, Laws 1912, Ch. 814; Plumbers, Code 191 1, Art. 43, Sees. 223- 
 229, with exceptions contained in Laws 1912, Chs. 764, 845; Station- 
 ary Lngineers, Baltimore City Code 1906, Sec. 427, as amended by 
 Laws 1910, Ch. 662, and Sec. 428.
 
 26 1 ] SOME MISCELLANEOUS LAWS II5 
 
 of course, only if employment at the time of the strike is at 
 a high ebb ; but employment usually is at a high ebb when a 
 strike is essayed, for this weapon is only efficient in pros- 
 perous times. The a priori argument advanced as to the 
 benefit to the unions of licensing laws seems again to be 
 borne out by the fact that most licensed occupations are 
 organized, though, here too, the argument is not conclusive 
 because of the probable functional relation of organization 
 and license laws. The argument based on the unorganized 
 condition of such licensed occupations as trained nurses and 
 chauffeurs, which is often used to offset that conclusion that 
 licensing and unionization are closely related, seems hardly 
 tenable because of the inherent nature of these occupations. 
 That licensing is not a sufficiently strong unionizing device 
 to unionize unorganizable occupations is freely conceded, 
 but it is nevertheless strongly maintained that it is a stimu- 
 lus towards organization. The desirability of unionization 
 by means of a licensing system is doubtful. It certainly 
 tends to make the union policy one of restriction rather 
 than of progress ; and if its effect is to cause the American 
 unions to pattern their policy after that of the British 
 unions, it is open to strong disapprobation. 
 
 The administration of these laws is not of much impor- 
 tance in this study and as it is practically the same in all 
 the laws, one explanation will suffice. Except for the chauf- 
 feurs, where the administration is quite naturally in the 
 hands of the automobile commissioner, all of the laws are 
 enforced by a board generally of men practiced in the regu- 
 lated occupation and generally appointed by the governor. 
 The meetings of this board are in most cases left to the dis- 
 cretion of the board itself, though sometimes a minimum is 
 fixed and sometimes, even in general laws, a certain number 
 of meetings must be held in Baltimore. The members of 
 the board are usually paid a per diem and travelling ex- 
 penses to be obtained from the fees of the applicants for 
 licenses. The board is allowed full discretion in setting the 
 examination where an examination is required, and this dis-
 
 Il6 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [262 
 
 cretion seems well placed because of the practical training 
 of the members of the board. The applicant must qualify- 
 only once before the granting body, but in the case of 
 plumbers, moving picture operators and stationary engi- 
 neers the license is good for only one year and the worker 
 is of right entitled to a renewal upon the payment of a re- 
 newal fee. There has been some litigation as to the inter- 
 pretation and application of these laws,^ but since these laws 
 are not of great importance in the sum total of labor legis- 
 lation of the State, the litigation needs no discussion. 
 
 Attachments and Liens. — There must next be considered 
 certain laws which, if not in all cases a protection of the 
 laborer, aim to further his welfare in legal proceedings. 
 Maryland does not hold any peculiar position in regard to 
 these laws, neither above nor below the average, for it has 
 been generally agreed that they are just and necessary and, 
 in most States, are of the same general nature. They in- 
 clude mechanics' lien laws, laws preferring wages in assign- 
 ments and similar laws. These laws are justified upon the 
 ground that the workingman, since he must always work a 
 certain length of time before he receives his wages, is al- 
 ways to a degree involuntarily in the debt of his employer. 
 The employer really stands more in the nature of a trustee 
 to the workingman than of a debtor, for the laborer hardly 
 looks upon his contract as one in which he extends credit 
 to the employer. It is right, therefore, that the laborer 
 should have greater security for his wages than the ordi- 
 nary debtor for his debt. The truck laws, which have al- 
 ready been considered, are a related branch of legislation, 
 which seems proper irrespective of the conditions of the 
 laborers as a class. 
 
 In pursuance of this policy, the Maryland legislature 
 early began to accumulate these laws on the statute books. 
 Thus there are mechanics' liens extending to buildings, ma- 
 
 » Concerning the plumber law, see Davidson v. State, 77 Md. 388. 
 Md 88 '"^^'■P''^*^*-'*°" °^ ^^^ ^^'■ber law, see State v. Tag, 100
 
 263] SOME MISCELLANEOUS LAWS II7 
 
 chines, wharves, bridges, boats" and even wells in Garrett 
 County,'' giving to those engaged in the construction of these 
 structures priority in the security for their wages over all 
 except in the case of vessels, prior mortgages and sales. So 
 also, in insolvency assignments, wages due for not more 
 than three months are preferred to all claims except prior 
 recorded liens on the property f and in an execution against 
 property in Alleghany and Garrett counties sufficient of this 
 property is exempted to pay all wage claims.'' In a differ- 
 ent spirit but again from public policy toward all and not 
 toward a class is the exemption of all tools and mechanical 
 instruments from execution on a judgment. ^^ Still differ- 
 ent and really quite without the scope of labor legislation 
 are those laws regulating strictly the attachment" and as- 
 signment^' of wages. These last are merely mentioned 
 because the words " wages " or " laborer " occurs in them 
 and, therefore, necessarily the workingman is affected by 
 them ; they are not social legislation to so great an extent 
 as are those, for example, preferring the laborer in insol- 
 vency. 
 
 Child Welfare. — A third group of laws deal with chil- 
 dren, apprenticeship and education. Their philosophy is 
 the same as that of the laws considered in the preceding 
 chapter, which the State has enacted in conservation of child 
 life. Their subject matter, however, is not the relation of 
 employer and employee, but the policy of the State toward 
 its children and, hence, is not included in the terms of 
 employment. 
 
 Historically, the apprentice law came first. When it is 
 remembered that the first Maryland enactment of this kind 
 was as early as 1715,^* it is hardly necessary to explain 
 
 *Code 191 1, Art. 63, Sees. 1-52. 
 
 ■^ Laws 1894, Ch. 608. 
 
 ^ Code 1911, Art. 47, Sec. 15. 
 
 » Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art, 1, Sec. 193 ; Art. 12, Sec. 149. 
 
 10 Code 1911, Art. 83, Sec. 10. 
 
 1^ Code 191 1, Art. 9, Sees. 33-34. 
 
 12 Code 1911, Art. 8, Sees. 11-17. 
 
 13 See Laws 1715, Ch. 19.
 
 Il8 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [264 
 
 that the State has not seen fit to regulate the terms of ap- 
 prenticeship, which it has properly left to the individual and 
 especially the union, but has merely laid down the funda- 
 mental principles upon which the contract or status of ap- 
 prenticeship is based. The law as it now stands," for in- 
 stance, allows the father, but not the mother,^^ to bind out 
 a minor child until the age of twenty-one in the case of 
 males and eighteen in that of females. The Orphans' Court 
 may also bind out for the same term any orphan whose in- 
 heritance is not sufficient to support him, or any other child 
 whose parents fail or are unable to support him. Of course 
 the prohibitions against child labor are binding upon the 
 Orphans' Court. 
 
 Then there is the elaborate school attendance law" of 
 1912 which was passed in connection with the child labor 
 law of that year and which requires every child not men- 
 tally deficient between the ages of eight and fourteen to 
 attend school throughout the entire session, and also every 
 child between the ages of fourteen and sixteen unless he 
 has been granted an employment certificate. An efficient 
 and complete administration has been provided in this act 
 and in these respects it is perfectly adequate. The useful- 
 ness of the act, however, depends upon the general useful- 
 ness of the school system, and although the Maryland school 
 system is perhaps above the average, it still falls short of 
 the highest standards. Without going beyond the scope of 
 this study mention may be made of the schools of mining 
 which have been authorized in Alleghany County for the 
 large mining population of that county.^^ 
 
 The latest activity of the State in the field of child wel- 
 fare is the limited mothers' pension law of 1916." Here 
 again we have a stretching of the function of the State 
 until it verges rather dangerously upon socialism. The law, 
 
 i*Code 191 1, Art. 6. 
 
 13 Baker v. Lauterback, 68 Md. 69. 
 
 1^ Laws 1912, Ch. 173. 
 
 1^ Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art. i, Sees. 218-225. 
 
 1* Laws 1916, Ch. 670.
 
 265] SOME MISCELLANEOUS LAWS II9 
 
 however, though properly classed as social legislation, is 
 hardly in the rubric of labor legislation, and an intensive 
 examination of its philosophy would be superfluous. " Any 
 mother of a child or children under the age of fourteen 
 years, whose husband is dead, and who is unable to support 
 it or them and maintain her home" may apply for relief 
 to the county commissioners in the counties or to the special 
 Board for Mothers' Rehef for Baltimore City. If, after in- 
 vestigation, it is found "that unless relief is granted, the 
 mother will be unable to support and educate her children, 
 and that they may become a public charge," she is referred 
 to the Juvenile Court which may order to be paid her twelve 
 dollars per month for the oldest child, ten dollars for the 
 next, and six dollars for each additional child up to forty 
 dollars a month. The administrative agency is to keep in 
 touch with its dependents, to visit them at least once every 
 two months, and to see that the relief is properly applied 
 for the welfare of the children. 
 
 State Employment. — The last series of laws which fall 
 into a clearly defined group are those laws in which the 
 State regulates the terms of employment of its own em- 
 ployees or those of its subdivisions. In the United States 
 this kind of legislation is generally political in its nature, 
 it is generally passed primarily as a bid for the labor vote 
 and only secondarily as a social measure ; but on the Conti- 
 nent, in Germany particularly, this species of legislation 
 plays an important part in the administrative organization 
 of the country. 
 
 In the first place, it has been decreed that preference 
 shall be given to voters in filling the jobs on the public work 
 of Baltimore City." A probable reason for this law is to 
 enable the party in control of the city government to use 
 the city's money for electioneering purposes. The other 
 laws regulating this subject are not so brazen, yet their 
 political effect is as certain. " For all laborers, workmen 
 or mechanics who may be employed by or on behalf of the 
 
 ^3 Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 35, Sec. 6.
 
 I20 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [266 
 
 Mayor and City Council of Baltimore," eight hours shall 
 constitute a day's work except in emergencies. Moreover, 
 " the rate of per diem wages paid to laborers, workmen or 
 mechanics employed directly by the Mayor, etc., shall not 
 be less than two dollars per diem," and where the work is 
 contracted out " not less than the current rate of per diem 
 wages in the locality where the work is performed shall be 
 paid " f° and these wages shall be paid weekly. ^^ This leg- 
 islation has always been upheld as constitutional, but it 
 hardly seems that the State is performing a proper legisla- 
 tive function in enacting these laws. It is quite true 
 that the State has a right to stipulate in its contracts any 
 terms that it wishes, but efficiency demands that an admin- 
 istrative head have some discretion in respect to the terms 
 of employment which he contracts for. The laborer would 
 hardly suffer from the exercise of administrative discre- 
 tion and its resulting elasticity. Yet it must be admitted 
 that practically every State of the Union has fek the neces- 
 sity of enacting legislation of this type. 
 
 Massachusetts State employment legislation represents a 
 more extreme type. Superficially it may seem a startling 
 step towards socialism, but on closer examination it seems 
 to have been an attempt to secure efficient administration. 
 It is aimed at attaining that thing, so harsh-sounding to the 
 democratic ear, yet seeming so necessary in a representative 
 government, a bureaucracy. In the first place, a civil service 
 examination must be passed before one is eligible for a state 
 job." Then to secure some sort of permanency in state 
 employment and to make this employment more attractive, 
 a state-aided old-age pension scheme is devised for state, 
 county and city employees.^^ It is a well-known fact that 
 Massachusetts has a very efficient government. How far 
 Its efficiency is due to the measures just mentioned is diffi- 
 
 20 Laws 1910, Ch. 94, Sec. 2. 
 " Baltimore City Code 1906, Sec. 47. 
 " Massachusetts Revised Laws 1902, Ch. 19, Sees. 12-13. 
 Mass. Laws 1910, Ch. 559; Laws 191 1, Ch. 532.
 
 267] SOME MISCELLANEOUS LAWS 121 
 
 cult to estimate ; but in view of European experience it 
 seems that something hke the Massachusetts plan is neces- 
 sary to invigorate American administration. 
 
 Laws which defy classification are : the Sunday rest law,^* 
 the law establishing Labor Day,^° a law requiring every 
 employer to allow all of his employees sufficient time for 
 voting at all elections,^® and a law of 191 2 requiring physi- 
 cians to report all cases of occupational sickness which they 
 are called upon to attend.-^ The last named law as it now 
 stands is designed merely for statistical purposes ; but since 
 it may lead to greater things in the way of the prevention 
 of occupational diseases it is properly treated as a labor en- 
 actment. Finally, in pursuance of the special care which 
 the law has always had for seamen, there is on the Mary- 
 land books a law protecting them from the solicitations of 
 any kind of sailors' employment agencies.^* 
 
 24 Code 1914, Art. 27, Sec. 435. 
 
 25 Baltimore City Code 1906, Art. 15, Sec. 2. 
 
 26 Code 1911, Art. 33, Sec. 91. 
 
 27 Laws 1912, Ch, 165, Sec. 5A. 
 
 28 Code 191 1, Art. 84, Sees. 1-7.
 
 CHAPTER VII 
 The Administrative System 
 
 The lawyer usually feels that administration and law are 
 things apart and a legal treatise generally contents itself 
 with a consideration of the substantive law, leaving admin- 
 istration to the care of the social reformer. With the ex- 
 ception of the law of the labor union, however, the present 
 study has been confined to the analysis of the works of 
 social reformers. Moreover, we have been dealing with the 
 science of legislation quite as much as with the science of 
 law, and legislation generally includes administration. The 
 common law and most codifying legislation is remedial, 
 compensatory; labor legislation is restrictive, prohibitive. 
 Labor legislation, though it is often attacked as class legis- 
 lation in its narrow and obnoxious sense, is in reality en- 
 acted for the benefit of the community as a whole; its vio- 
 lation is more in the nature of a crime against the state 
 than an injury to the individual. In the community, there- 
 fore, lies the responsibility of guarding against the viola- 
 tion of this legislation, against the slightest deviation from 
 its prescriptions. In the community, not in the individual, 
 must rest the initiative of bringing this law into operation. 
 
 An adequate labor law is accordingly dependent upon 
 efficient administrative provisions. As a chain is no stronger 
 than its weakest link, neither is labor legislation more effi- 
 cacious than its administrative system. Considering Mary- 
 land legislation from the standpoint of administrative effi- 
 ciency one cannot grant it high rank. Even the greatest 
 optimist would find himself somewhat doubtful, to say the 
 least, of the sagacity of the sovereign people of Maryland 
 after a talk with those charged with the administration of 
 the labor law. In order to give this subject adequate treat- 
 
 122
 
 269] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 1 23 
 
 ment in this study, it has seemed best to give first a com- 
 plete description of the administration as it now exists and 
 has existed, refraining as far as possible from any critical 
 comment. Having tried to understand the existing system, 
 we shall subject it to criticism and then attempt to outline 
 an adequate scheme of administration. 
 
 Before going any further, it must be understood, the 
 title of this chapter to the contrary notwithstanding, that 
 there is no administrative system for carrying out the labor 
 laws of Maryland. Administration there is, but system — 
 hardly. This criticism, of course, has been partly met by the 
 legislation of 1916; but this reform — for reform it was — 
 hardly necessitates any qualification of the statement that 
 Maryland, like most other American States, is happy-go- 
 lucky when it comes to legislating. A preconceived system 
 is rarely, if ever, thought out. An evil arises ; it is legis- 
 lated against; and, if administration must be provided for, 
 a special official or board is designated. That is what has 
 happened in the labor legislation. In spite of the recent 
 centralizing amendment, there are still eight separate and 
 distinct administrative agencies for Maryland labor law, 
 only one of which, the State Board of Labor and Statistics, 
 is charged with the administration of more than one law. 
 Besides this board, there are the State Board of Health, 
 the city inspector of buildings, the city health commissioner, 
 the Industrial Accident Commission — all real administrative 
 devices, and the police marshals, the constable of Carroll 
 County, and the city collector of water rents, who perform 
 administrative functions in connection with the labor law. 
 
 State Board of Labor and Statistics. — By far the most 
 important administrative agency is the State Board of Labor 
 and Statistics. This, by the act of 1916,^ is the Maryland 
 equivalent of a labor department, though still a rather cir- 
 cumscribed equivalent. It is the successor to and an im- 
 provement upon the old Bureau of Statistics and Informa- 
 
 1 Laws 1916, Ch. 406.
 
 124 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2/0 
 
 tion, which, as originally established in 1884,- was hardly 
 more than what its name implies, a bureau for the dissemi- 
 nation of information, but which by gradual accretion and 
 the accompanying process of selection was burdened more 
 and more with the enforcement of the labor law, until within 
 the last two or three years it had come to confine itself en- 
 tirely to labor problems. The new state board is, of course, 
 entirely devoted to labor problems. The old bureau was 
 the only centralizing influence in the Maryland labor law 
 and the endeavor of the legislation of 1916 was to increase 
 this centralization. 
 
 The State Board of Labor and Statistics is composed of 
 three commissioners appointed by the governor for a two- 
 year term. One of the commissioners is designated chair- 
 man by the governor at a salary of twenty-five hundred dol- 
 lars and the other two are merely advisory members of the 
 board. The chairman is the executive head of the board 
 and most of the activities of the department are directed by 
 him personally. The board as a whole meets only once 
 a month to determine the policy of the department. Its 
 business, however, is, it would seem, more to ratify the acts 
 of the chairman than to lay down any positive policy, for 
 the chairman with his more intimate knowledge of the af- 
 fairs of the department should be able to dictate rather 
 eflfectively the administrative program of the board. This 
 is especially so for the reason that the duties of the board 
 are not administrative in the broader sense, as described in 
 the fourth chapter, but are almost entirely executive. The 
 Maryland legislature followed the plans of New York and 
 Massachusetts, but did not give the commissioners the ad- 
 ministrative powers which they have in those States. The 
 board is a good beginning, but as the law now stands, the 
 two advisory members seem somewhat superfluous. 
 
 "The State Board of Labor and Statistics is authorized 
 and empowered to appoint . . . such deputies, inspectors, 
 assistants, and employees of every kind as may be necessary 
 
 2 Laws 1884, Ch. 211 ; Code 1911, Art. 89, Sec. i.
 
 2/1] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 125 
 
 for the performance of the duties now or hereafter imposed 
 upon it," provided, however, that all appointments shall be 
 subject to the approval of the governor.^ The board has 
 now* sixteen employees, including two medical examiners, 
 two boiler inspectors, two mining inspectors, its regular in- 
 spectors, officers to issue child labor permits, clerks and 
 stenographers. These positions are all frankly regarded 
 as political plums. The only qualification needed by an ap- 
 plicant is sufficient political " pull " in his or her ward. Not 
 only that, but since the board cannot hire the cheapest ser- 
 vice without the approval of the governor, it results that 
 when once employed, it is impossible to discharge for any 
 reason an inspector upon whom the party in power depends 
 to carry his ward. This is absolutely true of the men em- 
 ployed in the department. The women, it is said, are easier 
 to remove on account of inefficiency because they do not 
 swing so many votes. Moreover, I have been told, though 
 my informant is a woman, the then assistant-chief of the 
 old bureau, that as a whole the women are more likely to 
 be efficient than the men ; and certainly they take their work 
 more seriously. Yet it cannot be proposed that all the in- 
 spectors should be women, for men are required for some 
 jobs. About half the employees of the board are women. 
 The duties of the board are many and varied. Inherited 
 from the old bureau is its duty to collect and disseminate 
 information. The board is " to collect statistics and ex- 
 amine into the condition of labor in this State, with especial 
 reference to wages, and the causes of strikes and disagree- 
 ments between employers and employees."^ In the law are 
 set forth many other matters of economic interest concern- 
 ing which the board is ordered to investigate and publish 
 information, but of late the board has confined itself rather 
 closely to labor conditions. In pursuance of the duty im- 
 posed upon it by these sections of the law, the board pub- 
 lishes annually a lengthy report to the governor. 
 
 3 Laws 1916, Ch. 406, Sec. i, Par. 3. 
 
 *July, 1916. 
 
 5 Code 191 1, Art. 89, Sec. 2; Laws 1888, Ch. 173.
 
 126 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2/2 
 
 The board is also empowered " to organize, establish and 
 conduct free employment agencies, in such parts of the 
 State as it may deem advisable, for the free use of the citi- 
 zens of the State. "^ This is a great improvement over the 
 old law, which provided for only one agency, but it is still 
 deficient in that the legislature does not seem to realize the 
 seriousness of the problem of unemployment. It is now 
 usually held that a system of free employment offices which 
 aims to increase the fluidity of the labor market is one of the 
 most efficient remedies of unemployment.'^ As a conse- 
 quence of this, the State should expend every means to fur- 
 nish the most adequate system. This Maryland has hardly 
 done. The board has established agencies in Baltimore, 
 Cumberland, Hagerstown and on the Eastern Shore, but 
 these agencies are not closely enough coordinated. In con- 
 nection with the establishment of free employment agen- 
 cies, the board should have the licensing and supervision 
 of private employment agencies; but this power is vested in 
 the city collector of water rents.* 
 
 The state board, it will be remembered, has also in its 
 charge the administration of the law providing for the set- 
 tlement of labor disputes.^ 
 
 The chief duty of the board, however, is the inspection 
 of factories and workshops. There are three inspection 
 laws which the board enforces, the factory inspection and 
 industrial registration law, the child labor law, and the 
 women's ten-hour law. For this inspection the board has 
 appointed five inspectors in Baltimore City, one, with the 
 possibility of an increase to two in Western Maryland, and 
 one on the Eastern Shore, each at a salary of about one 
 thousand dollars. For the purposes of this inspection, Bal- 
 
 « Code 191 1, Art. 89, Sec. 2, Par. 7, as amended by Laws 1916, Ch. 
 406, Sec. 2. 
 
 J For a full treatment of this subject, see an article on state em- 
 ployment agencies by Wm. M. Leiserson in 29 Political Science 
 Quarterly, p. 28. 
 
 8 Ordinances of Mayor and City Council of Baltimore, 1909-10, 
 No. 433. "^"^ 
 
 » See Chapter II.
 
 273] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 12/ 
 
 timore is divided into five districts, each of which is as- 
 signed to an inspector who is responsible for the inspection 
 and conditions in his district. How this responsibiHty is 
 enforced has not yet been worked out and seems to be in 
 a rather vague state, but a system of checking up could be 
 easily instituted. But this localization of the work of an 
 inspector can lead to valuable results if the inspector by 
 frequent visits can get into friendly relations with the em- 
 ployer and persuade rather than force him to better the 
 conditions of his plant. It is doubtful whether this con- 
 summation can be attained under the present law, but the 
 beginning is worth while. In the first place, the laws as 
 they now exist lay down exact rules and leave nothing to 
 the discretion of the board or inspector, and the instruc- 
 tions given to the inspectors accentuate the routine charac- 
 ter of their work. In the second place, the inspector has 
 to inspect in pursuance of three separate acts and it seems 
 that the districts will be too large for the intensive inspec- 
 tion that this plan requires. It is doubtful in fact whether 
 five inspectors are sufficient for the minimum efficiency of 
 the laws. Finally, the character of the inspectors who are 
 political appointees of doubtful efficiency is such as to make 
 decidedly improbable the attainment of the best results and 
 to render doubtful the careful inspection which the laws 
 require. 
 
 Turning now to the first of these laws which the board 
 enforces, the factory inspection and industrial registration 
 law,^" we shall examine the administration of it in detail 
 before considering the other two laws. It has already been 
 said that the inspection facilities for the enforcement of this 
 law are deficient both in quantity and quality ; but even 
 with four or five inspections per shop a year by trained in- 
 spectors, which would furnish an adequate inspection, it is 
 doubtful whether this act could reach the pinnacle of effi- 
 ciency. As far as obtaining information and statistics from 
 the employers and workers covered by this act, the board 
 
 i** Laws 1914, Ch. 779.
 
 128 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [274 
 
 has full and discretionary authority, and the reports in this 
 respect are valuable, notwithstanding their incompleteness 
 due to the shiftless methods of the inspectors. When, how- 
 ever, the actual enforcement of the sanitary and safety pro- 
 visions of the law is considered it is obvious that the di- 
 vision of authority in the enforcement of this act makes 
 completeness impossible. 
 
 When the inspectors are sent out on their tours of inves- 
 tigation, their duty is to visit and inspect thoroughly every 
 factory, workshop or tenement shop in the territory to which 
 they have been assigned. Upon visiting the work place the 
 inspector notes the toilet conditions, the presence of fire- 
 escapes and the location of staircases, the existence of any 
 communicable disease, and, if the shop savors to the least 
 degree of tenement or loft shop, the inspector further meas- 
 ures the cubic capacity of the room. This is the routine 
 whether the inspection be within the regular investigation 
 or whether it be undertaken upon the application of a home- 
 worker for a license for his shop. The standards of the 
 inspection are the same in both cases, for the license, as 
 will be remembered, is revocable at any time by the board. 
 After completing the investigating for the day, the inspector 
 returns to the office and notes the results of his inspection 
 on the forms provided for filing. That is as far as the in- 
 spector goes. 
 
 The report as thus filed is subject to the authority of 
 three separate administrative agencies. The board has the 
 power in itself to enforce only the provision limiting the 
 number of persons employed in any room to one to each 
 five hundred cubic feet of air space. If the shop inspected 
 seems to lack adequate fire-escapes required by law, the 
 report is referred to the city inspector of buildings. In hrm 
 is vested the duty of visiting and inspecting all manufac- 
 tories employing twenty-five or more persons and of ruling 
 on the adequacy of fire-escapes." Neither of these duties 
 
 " Baltimore City Charter 1915, Sees. 80-81 ; Ordinances of Balti- 
 more, 1908-09, No. 155, Sec. 3, Pars. 6-7; Laws 1908, Ch. 495.
 
 2/5] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 1 29 
 
 is very strictly enforced. The inspection he leaves entirely 
 in the hands of the State Board of Labor and Statistics, and 
 perhaps it is better so, although the city department has, in 
 fact, a number of inspectors. The provisions for fire- 
 escapes are interpreted so loosely that, as has been said, 
 they are considered fulfilled if the house in which the shop 
 is located has two staircases of any kind in different parts 
 of the building or one central staircase. The result of this 
 division of authority, as is always the case, is that the law 
 is practically nullified. The state board is afraid, and in 
 truth is hardly empowered, to make more stringent regula- 
 tions than those of the city building inspector, so that here 
 there is no compelling authority. The building inspector, 
 on the other hand, does not consider himself delegated with 
 any authority to protect the safety of the employees. As 
 the secretary of the department once said: "Oh, no; we 
 don't make any trouble. We are a kind of complaint de- 
 partment. The fire department and the labor department 
 send us their complaints and we try to straighten them 
 out." The "straightening" is hardly in the direction of 
 strictness. 
 
 As for the sanitary conditions of the shop, or tenement, 
 a different course of proceeding is established. In the first 
 place, it is provided by statute that before any license for a 
 tenement is issued the records of the local health depart- 
 ment shall be investigated, and if they show " the presence 
 of any infectious, contagious or communicable disease, or 
 the existence of any unsanitary conditions," the license may 
 be refused without any inspection of the room or apart- 
 ment. Usually, however, the room or shop is investigated, 
 and then the report referred to the local health department. 
 If the health department finds from its own records and the 
 report of the inspector that the place is sanitary, a license is 
 always issued by the board, for in this case as in others the 
 board refuses to adopt any higher standard than that set 
 by the more technical local department and here again the 
 standard is low. If the health department, on the other 
 9
 
 1^0 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2/6 
 
 hand, finds from an examination of the records and report 
 that the place is below the minimum, the license is with- 
 held until these defects are remedied, and even then it is 
 not issued until the approval of the health department is 
 obtained. 
 
 It is obvious from what has been said that however good 
 this law may be in its substantive provisions and however 
 complete may be the records obtained under this act, in final 
 results, because of the great division of administrative re- 
 sponsibility and the inefficiency of the personnel to which 
 is entrusted the enforcement, the law fails to realize a large 
 amount of its potential value. 
 
 Next in importance to the factory inspection law is the 
 recent child labor law.^^ As has been said in a previous 
 chapter, this is a most valuable act and in draftsmanship 
 one of the best on the statute book. The act goes into great 
 detail in establishing administrative provisions for its en- 
 forcement and an exhaustive study might profitably be 
 made of these administrative details ; but it will serve our 
 purpose in the general estimate of the Maryland system of 
 labor law administration merely to point out the salient 
 features of these administrative provisions. 
 
 After the inspections under the factory law, the next duty 
 of the inspectors is to investigate the ages and conditions of 
 employment of children. The inspection under this law 
 should be more efficient than under the law which we have 
 just been considering, for no skill is required and no tech- 
 nical training necessary. Even a political appointee should 
 be able to prepare a complete report. The task of the in- 
 spector is merely to see that the employer complies with 
 certain provisions, such as the keeping of a registry, to ex- 
 amine the certificates of any children who are below six- 
 teen, to ascertain the true age of any child who appears 
 younger than sixteen, the employer being compelled to fur- 
 nish within fifteen days satisfactory evidence that a child 
 apparently under sixteen is in fact over sixteen or to cease 
 
 12 Laws 1912, Ch. 731, as amended in 1916.
 
 277] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM I3I 
 
 to employ that child ;" and, finally, to tabulate the number 
 of children employed in the various occupations in the fac- 
 tory. If any child is employed in an occupation below the 
 age which the law provides, the inspector will notify and 
 warn the employer, but usually prosecutions and the pre- 
 liminaries are managed from the home office. One of the 
 child labor inspectors under the old bureau had in practice 
 been found to be more efficient than the others and she had 
 been assigned to investigational work similar to that per- 
 formed by the British lady inspectors. One section of the 
 law^* prohibits the employment of children under sixteen in 
 certain specified employments or " in any other occupation 
 dangerous to life and limb, or injurious to the health or 
 morals of such child." Instead of leaving the interpreta- 
 tion of this section to the discretion of the individual in- 
 spector, the bureau had assigned this more efficient inspector 
 to the work of ascertaining what are dangerous occupations 
 and was to issue administrative orders on the basis of this 
 investigation. This was really a notable step in advance 
 and fuller mention will be made of it later. It is to be 
 hoped that it will be developed further by the state board. 
 The task of issuing employment certificates and street 
 trade badges is a somewhat heavy one and when the act 
 first went into force the offices of the old bureau were 
 gwamped with applicants. Detailed provisions are made 
 in the act as to the requirements which must be fulfilled 
 before these permits are issued and granting them is not an 
 indiscriminate, clerical operation. In Baltimore City the 
 hoard is empowered to issue these employment certificates, 
 and in the counties the county superintendent of schools has 
 concurrent jurisdiction with it. In the offices of the state 
 board there is a special inspector at a higher salary, whose 
 only work is to issue these certificates and to keep a file of 
 the duplicates. The two physicians, also, earn their pay 
 merely by examining applicants for certificates. The re- 
 
 13 Ibid., Sec. 19. 
 " Ibid., Sec. 8.
 
 132 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [2/8 
 
 ports of these examinations promise to become valuable 
 sociological statistics. In reality, the board issues the great 
 majority of the employment certificates for city and coun- 
 ties ; but when the school superintendent issues a certificate 
 in one of the counties he is empowered to employ a physi- 
 cian at a stipulated fee to make the examination and is re- 
 quired to transmit all records to the board. One of the 
 child labor inspectors is detailed to take charge of the issu- 
 ing of badges to boys under sixteen engaged in street trade. 
 
 Both in administrative provisions and administrative 
 practice this is one of the most satisfactory and efficient 
 laws in the Maryland labor code. Nevertheless, there is one 
 defect, perhaps practically unavoidable. This law and the 
 compulsory school attendance law dovetail exactly and, in 
 fact, the enforcement of these laws is indiscriminately con- 
 fided to attendance officers and inspectors from the State 
 Board of Labor and Statistics. The attendance officers and 
 the inspectors are responsible and report to different chiefs 
 who are themselves in no way related and have no official 
 correspondence. It seems that here a valuable opportunity 
 to check up results has been lost. 
 
 The other inspection law enforced by the state board, the 
 women's ten-hour law,^^ has no interesting administrative 
 features. The inspector merely notices that the substan- 
 tive provisions of the law, such as the posting of schedules, 
 are obeyed. This law, for political reasons, was formerly 
 enforced by a special bureau composed only of women. 
 One of the most obvious reforms of the 1916 amendment 
 was the placing of the administration of this law under the 
 supervision of the same agency which enforced the child 
 labor law. 
 
 Two other inspection laws were brought under the in- 
 direct control of the State Board of Labor and Statistics 
 by the 1916 legislature. The board with the approval of the 
 governor appoints two boiler inspectors for Baltimore City" 
 
 II D^i^^ ^^^^' ^^- 79. as amended in 1914 and 1916. 
 1016 Ch """^ ^'^^ Charter 1915, Sees. 572-589, as amended by Laws
 
 2/9] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 1 33 
 
 and a mine inspector for Alleghany and one for Garrett 
 County.^'' Aside from this power of appointment and the 
 fact that the board supplies the boiler inspectors with office 
 rooms and receives annual reports from these officers, there 
 is no coordination between these separate agencies. The 
 legislature attempted to introduce a centralized system, but 
 merely centralized the structure, not the system. The boiler 
 inspection and the mine inspection laws have not been 
 changed by the amalgamation. The inspectors under these 
 laws are also political appointees, but the mine inspectors 
 must "possess a competent and practical knowledge of the 
 different systems of mining and [ventilation] . . . and of 
 the nature and constituent parts of the various gases found 
 in coal mines . . . and shall have had five years' practical 
 experience as a miner." In his reports he is to make rec- 
 ommendations for future legislation for safety in mining.^' 
 
 Finally, every physician attending a patient suffering 
 from any occupational disease must make a full report to 
 the state board which publishes the results in its annual 
 report.^^ Though a minor provision, it has possibilities and 
 already the reports make interesting reading. 
 
 State Board of Health. — Related to the work of the board 
 of labor is the work of the State Board of Health in enforc- 
 ing the Sanitary Inspection Law.^" This law applies only 
 to shops and factories manufacturing or handling food 
 stuffs and, as the bureau has nothing to do with these shops 
 except so far as they may be located in tenements or lofts, 
 there is not much overlapping in inspection. But, logically, 
 why should not this law be placed under the charge of the 
 State Board of Labor and Statistics, perhaps assisted by the 
 State Board of Health ? 
 
 The Sanitary Inspection Law, as will be remembered, 
 lays down numerous and definite specifications for the clean- 
 
 ^'' Code Public Local Laws 1888, Art i, Sec. 196, and Art. 12, Sec. 
 150, as amended by Laws 1902, Ch. 124, and Laws 1916, Ch. 410. 
 
 18 Laws 1916, Ch. 410. 
 
 19 Laws 1912, Ch. 165, Sec. 5A. 
 
 20 Laws 1914, Ch. 678.
 
 134 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [28O 
 
 liness and sanitary condition of factories or shops handling 
 food stuffs and more stringent rules for canneries. It is a 
 most carefully and scientifically drafted law. It may safely 
 be said to be in the highest rank among what may be called 
 regulative acts, a class of laws which, however, is giving 
 ■way to general laws with provisions for administrative or- 
 ders. The Maryland law does indeed include a provision 
 for these orders ; but, not being absolutely essential to the 
 working of the act, none have been issued. The inspectors 
 of the State Board of Health have, then, for their guidance 
 in the administration of the law the specifications included 
 within the body of the law and nothing else. True, these 
 specifications are rather searching and well-defined, but it 
 is impossible that even the legislature could have foreseen 
 all the contingencies in which the law might be called into 
 play. Accordingly, with respect to details too minute to 
 refer to the Board of Health, numerous disputes as to the 
 interpretation and application of the act must arise. The 
 inspector is thrown back upon his own discretion and the 
 law is strictly or loosely enforced according to the tempera- 
 ment of the inspector. Now it has not been possible for 
 me to interview the employers affected by this law, but from 
 the class of inspectors who are employed by the Board of 
 Health it would seem a fair deduction that the act is admin- 
 istered leniently rather than strictly. 
 
 The full control over the administration of this act has 
 been placed by the Board of Health practically in the hands 
 of one member of that board, who has also charge of the 
 enforcement of the Pure Food and Drugs Act. He com- 
 bines the work of enforcing the two laws and uses the same 
 inspectoral force for both. There are six inspectors 
 scattered over the State. Owing to the fact that their 
 work as pure food insepctors necessitates keeping their 
 identity unknown so far as possible, it is the endeavor of 
 the supervisor to have the same man visit a factory at as 
 infrequent intervals as possible. The inspections are fre- 
 quent, about four a year, but the continual switching around
 
 28 1] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM I 35 
 
 of inspectors offsets to a great degree the advantages to be 
 gained from frequent inspections, among the most impor- 
 tant of which are the famiHarity of the inspector with the 
 plant and his personal amicable relations with the owner. 
 It may be said here that the Board of Health is noted as 
 being of the various State departments one of those least 
 contaminated by politics, and the inspectors may be efficient 
 so far as the Pure Food Law is concerned, in connection 
 with which all the technical work is done at headquarters. 
 An inspector, however, who has no technical training, whose 
 salary ranges in the neighborhood of one thousand dollars, 
 for whom there is little or no hope of promotion, and who 
 has no assurances of permanency of employment, is not 
 one to whom should be entrusted the enforcement of pro- 
 visions calling for the cleanliness " which the nature of the 
 employment will permit " or the detection of communicable 
 diseases. The act suffers both in the nature of the admin- 
 istration and in the class of inspectors to whom its enforce- 
 ment is entrusted. 
 
 Minor Administrative Agencies. — The Industrial Acci- 
 dent Commission, which is charged with the administra- 
 tion of the workmen's compensation law, may be dismissed 
 with the statement that it is wholly separated from all 
 other labor law agencies in the State. Likewise separated 
 from any other agency is the Baltimore City Commissioner 
 of Health in his performance of the duty imposed upon 
 him to inspect all mercantile or manufacturing establish- 
 ments in Baltimore City where females are employed to 
 gee that seats are provided for these employees-^ — a need- 
 less overlapping upon the Women's Ten Hour Law inspec- 
 tion. Similarly isolated and overlapping, the constable of 
 Carroll County inspects the ventilation in stone grinding 
 mills^ — certainly an incongruous agency for the adminis- 
 tration of labor laws. Hardly less so, however, are the 
 
 21 Ordinances of Baltimore, 1910-1911, No. 547. 
 
 22 Laws 1894, Ch. 202.
 
 136 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [282 
 
 marshals of police or the police commissioners in their in- 
 spection of scaffoldings which are reported to be unsafe." 
 
 Suggestions for Reforms. — All the administrative agen- 
 cies charged with the enforcement of the Maryland labor 
 law have now been described or mentioned. On the whole 
 there is little less than absolute chaos. One department is 
 fairly well defined, but, on the whole, no more cohesion or 
 system is present than in a pan of peas. And yet the situa- 
 tion is not altogether hopeless. Other States have evolved 
 an orderly administration out of equally or more chaotic 
 labor laws upon a critical expose of that condition. It is 
 hoped that this criticism by merely reporting the results in 
 other States may lead to some such result in Maryland. 
 
 The first and cheapest reform needed is some method of 
 taking the personnel of the various departments out of poli- 
 tics. Much has already been said of the disastrous results 
 of the present methods of appointments to all positions in 
 the administration, so that only one instance further will 
 be cited. In 191 5 the elections for governor occurred on 
 the second of November and the term of office began on 
 January i, 1916. A Democratic governor was elected to 
 succeed a Republican. A week after the November elec- 
 tion I visited the Bureau of Statistics, as it then was, to in- 
 terview the assistant-chief. It was only half-past two in 
 the afternoon, yet there was not a single man in the office. 
 All the inspectors were Republicans and knew or thought 
 that they would lose their positions at the first of the year, 
 so they had practically refused to do any work at all. 
 
 It is perfectly obvious that some sort of civil service ap- 
 pointment is the prime essential to an efficient administra- 
 tion of the labor law. Whether this shall be by competi- 
 tive, technical examination or by qualifying, general exami- 
 nation with appointment vested in the head of the labor 
 department is a question somewhat outside the scope of this 
 study. The former has the advantage of securing techni- 
 cally efficient inspectors substantially freed from the taint 
 
 23 Code 191 1, Art. 48, Sees. 75-79.
 
 283] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 1 3/ 
 
 of politics ; the latter the advantage of securing all around 
 efficient inspectors who are also more subservient to and 
 often also more agreeable to the chiefs. The competitive 
 examination is perhaps more suited to the present status of 
 labor departments where there is a subdivision of functions 
 and where the inspectors are selected for one purpose alone 
 without much hope of promotion. The qualifying exami- 
 nation is more suited to the centralized system which has 
 been adopted wherever reform has been introduced, where 
 the inspector has various duties to perform in an inspectoral 
 way, where he must be acceptable in appearance and man- 
 ner to the employers, and where, moreover, as will soon be 
 seen, the appointment is guarded from politics by the na- 
 ture of the head of the department. 
 
 In addition to a civil service appointment, some means 
 must be provided to attract the desirable classes to the posi- 
 tions in the service. We can never in America hope to in- 
 spire in our citizens the regard for government service 
 which is present in the German, or perhaps even in the 
 English, heart ; but there is no reason why the government 
 service should not be lifted to a higher plane than that 
 which it now occupies. Salaries in the United States 
 compare most favorably with those abroad, so that there is 
 not much room for improvement in this direction without 
 involving great expense. Improvement is needed in re- 
 spect to the security of tenure, the opportunities for ad- 
 vancement, and the provisions for the disabilities of age or 
 accident. We have referred in the preceding chapter 
 apropos of the Massachusetts state pension law to the value 
 of a pension system for state employees as an incentive to 
 efficient administration ; but nowhere in the United States 
 does there seem to have been a proper appreciation of per- 
 manency and promotion as essentials in government employ- 
 ment. It is useless to press a priori arguments. In the 
 light of the wonderful success of the English system of gov- 
 ernment in general, one may demand, in the administration
 
 1^8 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [284 
 
 of the labor law, a graded system of inspectors with pro- 
 motion for eflficiency and permanency of service. 
 
 Nevertheless, such a statement of the principles of ad- 
 ministration calls for some qualification. There must be 
 considered the inevitable conflict of an independent, bureau- 
 cratic administration and a politically responsible adminis- 
 tration. Abstract questions would lead us too far afield; 
 so, concretely, should the heads of the various departments 
 be selected absolutely by the governor or should there be 
 promotion from the ranks ? As the labor administration is 
 now constituted, it would seem perfectly feasible to vest 
 the selection of the entire force in a civil service board. The 
 only reason for the political appointment of the various 
 chiefs would be to secure uniformity of policy and politi- 
 cal responsibility and neither of these is necessary in the 
 Maryland system: the only policy should be an absolutely 
 strict adherence to the terms of the law, and removal of 
 the chiefs for cause by the governor provides all the respon- 
 sibility which could reasonably be expected. It is perhaps 
 unfortunate that all of these administrative agencies are 
 directly subordinated to the governor and that there is no 
 intermediate state officer responsible for them to the gover- 
 nor, but this deficiency does not invalidate the proposal 
 that as now constituted the labor administration should be 
 entirely divorced from politics. Under the scheme of ad- 
 ministration which is now to be described, however, the 
 present heads of departments would be merely chiefs of 
 bureaus who could be efficiently chosen by promotion from 
 the ranks, whereas the head of the unified department of 
 labor, be it an individual or a commission, would be selected 
 by and responsible to the governor. Not only administra- 
 tively but also politically the centralized administrative sys- 
 tem is the more desirable. 
 
 What has been termed the centralized administrative 
 system has only recently made its appearance in American 
 labor legislation. Labor legislation in the United States 
 has been a gradual evolution without any preconceived
 
 285] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM 1 39 
 
 plan, so that the administrative result has been a hopeless 
 hodge-podge. Under the influence of the movement for 
 efficiency, several States have recently completely reorgan- 
 ized their labor law administrations into logical, central- 
 ized systems. This reorganization is precisely what Mary- 
 land needs. Civil service reform would work wonders 
 v/ith that vaguely outlined thing which has up till now 
 been termed the Maryland labor department or labor de- 
 partments, but to obtain real efficiency Maryland should 
 have a true Labor Department embracing all the adminis- 
 trative agencies enforcing laws throughout the State. Such 
 a reform would involve some additional expense, but ex- 
 actly how much is hard to calculate because there would 
 be a great saving in the elimination of overlapping func- 
 tions. Such a reform would place some additional burden 
 upon the legislature which initiates it, but, in establishing 
 an administrative system to which the administration of 
 any future labor law might in a few words be referred, it 
 would relieve subsequent legislatures. The investigating 
 commissions in New York and Illinois have recommended 
 reorganization of this kind, and sufficient has been written 
 about it to enable an amateur in administration to suggest 
 reforms for Maryland. 
 
 The reorganized Maryland Department of Labor should 
 be presided over by a commissioner or commission ap- 
 pointed by the governor. The head of the department 
 should be the only position filled by appointment. His 
 deputies, if there are any, the heads of the various bureaus, 
 the division chiefs, and the inspectors would be selected by 
 the merit system. In this way the English administrative 
 system would be approximated, that is, a political chief with 
 civil subordinates. If sufficient confidence can be placed in 
 the head of the department, he should be given the power 
 of choosing his subordinates from a list of qualified appli- 
 cants and this method is especially applicable to the chiefs 
 of bureaus who must have other qualifications than those 
 which can be ascertained by examination. Everything pos-
 
 140 
 
 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [286 
 
 sible should be done to bring about a condition in which 
 the head of the department will be fully trusted ; but, if he 
 is not, appointment to all subordinate positions should be 
 by competitive examination. 
 
 The Department of Labor should be divided into six 
 bureaus : the bureau of inspection, the bureau of statistics 
 and information, the bureau of arbitration and mediation, 
 the bureau of mines, the employment bureau, and the indus- 
 trial accident commission. The bureau of inspection would 
 be the most important of these and it might be feasible in 
 the present condition of the labor law to put in charge of 
 this bureau the Commissioner of Labor himself with the 
 aid of a deputy if necessary. 
 
 The bureau of inspection should be divided into five di- 
 visions : the division of factory inspection, the division of 
 home-work inspection, the division of mercantile inspection, 
 the division of steam boiler inspection, and the division of 
 industrial hygiene. It may be objected that this subdivision 
 is too minute for present conditions in Maryland. To a 
 certain degree the objection is valid : some of the divisions 
 may have little to do and one man may be sufficient to fill 
 them. This plan, however, is not to meet present condi- 
 tions only, but is to furnish a basis for all future labor leg- 
 islation, and we may be sure that future labor legislation 
 will be quantitatively greater than in the past. One of the 
 first duties of the legislature after reorganizing the admin- 
 istration should be to make some of the local laws state- 
 wide, for in the main they seem to have been enacted 
 locally because of the lack of state-wide administrative 
 agencies. Now the inspectors in the factory, home-work, 
 and mercantile divisions will all enforce practically the 
 same laws. The divisions will be upon the basis of places 
 inspected instead of laws enforced, and every inspector will 
 be authorized to enforce any law which is applicable to the 
 establishment which he is visiting. Moreover, entire au- 
 thority to enforce the laws must be centralized in the Labor 
 Department and all reference to local authorities must be
 
 287] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM I4I 
 
 discontinued; the Labor Department must be made self- 
 sufficient. Thus practically all overlapping will be elimi- 
 nated. 
 
 Of sufficient importance to be entitled to special mention 
 is the division of industrial hygiene, copied from the New 
 York division of the same name.^* It is what is popularly 
 known as a bureau of "theorists," a bureau of technical 
 experts, being composed in New York of a physician, a 
 chemical engineer, a mechanical engineer who is an expert 
 in ventilation and accident prevention, and a civil engineer 
 who is an expert in fire prevention and building construc- 
 tion. The duty of this division is to make inspections of a 
 highly technical nature, to make independent investigations 
 upon which laws and orders may be issued, and to serve as 
 general technical advisors to the department. This is an 
 expensive division, but it is a most valuable one. It would 
 be well if Maryland could copy the New York plan in its 
 entirety, but that is not a necessity. To begin with, Mary- 
 land would need at least one physician to supervise the issu- 
 ing of child-labor permits and the inspection of food- 
 producing establishments. The mechanical engineer would 
 be a valuable adjunct to the Industrial Accident Commis- 
 sion and the State Insurance Fund. 
 
 The other bureaus are less important. The bureau of 
 statistics and information should have the same functions 
 that that bureau originally exercised ; it should be the pub- 
 licity bureau of the department. The bureau of arbitration 
 and mediation should have the enforcement of the law 
 which is now entrusted to the State Board of Labor, to- 
 gether with the enforcement of any more efficient law 
 which might be enacted. The bureau of mines should be 
 charged with the enforcement of the mining law in the 
 western counties. The bureau of employment should be 
 charged with the establishment of free employment offices 
 and the licensing of private employment offices. The In- 
 
 24 New York Consolidated Laws, Ch. 31, Art. 4, Sec. 60, as amended 
 in 1913. Laws 1913, Ch. 145.
 
 142 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [288 
 
 dustrial Accident Commission, which has been placed as 
 the sixth bureau in the Labor Department, should hold a 
 relation to the department entirely different from the other 
 bureaus. For a number of reasons it is advisable that there 
 be some connection between this commission and the rest 
 of the department; but, owing- to the importance of the 
 commission and the class of men who are necessary for the 
 adequate administration of the compensation law, it is 
 doubtful if the commissioners should be made more than 
 nominally subordinate to the head of the department or if 
 they should be chosen in the same manner as are the chiefs 
 of the other bureaus. This is a practical question calling 
 for fuller discussion than can be given it here. 
 
 The question whether the administrative head of the 
 Department of Labor should be an individual or a commis- 
 sion has been complicated in most States where reorganiza- 
 tion has taken place by questions of legislative policy. Most 
 of these States have enacted general laws, with delegated 
 authority to issue specific orders, to take the place of the 
 detailed and intricate laws on their statute books. Enough 
 has already been said of the advantages of this mode of leg- 
 islation both from the substantive and the administrative 
 standpoint. From the point of view of administration, the 
 elimination of all discretion in the individual inspector and 
 the substitution of the educational, helpful attitude for the 
 antagonistic, prosecuting frame of mind are advantages so 
 manifest as to be undeniable. 
 
 For purely executive work, a one-man head is most de- 
 sirable, but if the head of the department has ordinance 
 powers some sort of commission is a logical necessity. Up 
 to the present time there have been devised four forms 
 which this commission might take. In the first place, the 
 Wisconsin plan places all the power, executive as well as 
 administrative, in the hands of a commission of three, an 
 excellent plan in most respects, but it has not been followed 
 and has been much criticised because of the weakness in- 
 herent in the division of executive authority. The second
 
 289] THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM I43 
 
 plan is the New York scheme adopted in 1913 under which 
 there is a single executive head, the commissioner, and an 
 advisory board of representative men and women not subor- 
 dinate to, but presided over by, the commissioner, which is 
 empowered to draft orders. The objection urged against 
 this plan is that which is urged against all part-time boards, 
 the objection of inefficiency. In the third place, a slight 
 variation of the New York plan is advocated, the single 
 executive head as before, but a commission composed of the 
 chiefs of bureaus. This is open to the serious objection that 
 it confers independent advisory and discretionary functions 
 upon officers who are administratively subordinate to the 
 head of the department and who are, moreover, civil ser- 
 vice appointees with technical proficiency, but hardly legis- 
 latively representative. The final plan is that advocated 
 by the Illinois Efficiency Commission of 1914. This retains 
 the single commissioner and associates with him two depu- 
 ties, free from executive duties and of equal rank with the 
 commissioner so far as ordinance power is concerned. 
 Aside from the possibility of friction, the overwhelming 
 objection to this scheme is the useless multiplication of 
 officers for an administration the size of Maryland's. 
 
 On the whole it would seem that the New York plan, 
 which has been adopted in a modified form by the 1916 
 amendment, is best adapted to the needs of Maryland. Be- 
 sides the commissioner, the board is composed of four mem- 
 bers, of whom it is advisable that one should be an em- 
 ployer of labor, one a wage-earner, one a physician or sani- 
 tary engineer, and one a woman. All of these offices should 
 be filled by appointment by the governor and the salaries 
 should be large enough to be attractive to the worthy and 
 the influential. For the conduct of its business the board 
 should meet once or twice a month at the call of the com- 
 missioner. Besides the work of formulating administrative 
 ordinances, the commissioner should lay before the board 
 all matters in which any policy or discretion is involved, 
 except as the exigencies of a particular case may call for
 
 1^4 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [29O 
 
 immediate action. The board should also have some ad- 
 visory power in the choice of subordinates, if these are 
 selected from a qualifying and not from a competitive ex- 
 amination. In general, however, except in the matter of 
 formulating ordinances, the board should be merely advis- 
 ory to the commissioner, for administrative responsibility 
 must be centered in one man and, in the last resort, the 
 commissioner himself must be directly responsible to the 
 governor. Centralization and discretionary power must 
 always be balanced by responsibility. 
 
 This brief outline I have built up almost entirely inde- 
 pendently of the 1916 reorganization of the Maryland labor 
 administration, the form of the head of the department and 
 the centralizing idea being the only similarities. I have been 
 forced to do this for the reason that the 1916 amendment, 
 although a good beginning, failed, like all pervious legisla- 
 tion, to take a large and comprehensive view of the situa- 
 tion. As has been said, by failing to go all the way it failed 
 to realize many of its possibilities. Instead of looking to 
 the future, the legislature only strove to correct some of 
 the defects of the past, and accordingly future legislatures 
 will have almost as much difficulty in attaching new duties 
 to the state board as it did to the old bureau. The plan 
 presented in this chapter is based upon scientific investiga- 
 tions conducted in the most advanced States ; and while no 
 scheme can be unalterable, this one has been elaborated 
 with as much prevision as mankind is capable of.
 
 CHAPTER VIII 
 The State in Relation to Labor 
 
 It seems rather preposterous after the description of the 
 administration of the Maryland labor law given in the last 
 chapter to repeat what was said in the first chapter, that 
 Maryland is an average American State so far as its labor 
 law is concerned. Yet calmer consideration will justify this 
 statement. The administration, it must be admitted, is in- 
 ferior, though the system of administration which is provided 
 by statute might be made comparatively efficient. Equally 
 poor are the safety and sanitary inspection laws with the 
 exception of the recent sanitary provisions for food manu- 
 facturing establishments. Slightly better are the laws regu- 
 lating the terms of employment of adult men, though, it 
 must be remembered, these laws have far from justified 
 their enactment. The other provisions of the labor law are 
 above the average. The child labor law and the workmen's 
 compensation law, though perhaps capable of improvement, 
 are really exemplary pieces of legislation. The industrial 
 disputes act and the other laws relating to the labor union 
 are almost as good as could be hoped for. The women's 
 ten-hour law ranks lower than similar laws in many States, 
 but nevertheless Maryland is above the average. The non- 
 statutory law of the labor union, while not ideal and not 
 even satisfactory under present conditions, is in absolute 
 accord with the best legal thought. 
 
 In spite of the fact that Maryland deserves such a rank, 
 a general survey of the labor law is likely to be most dis- 
 appointing. The labor law considered as a whole displays 
 the same lack of system that was evident in the administra- 
 tion of that law. The legislature churns out haphazardly 
 all kinds of labor law and when the student tries to unearth 
 lo 145
 
 146 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [292 
 
 some maxims or some philosophy upon which the legisla- 
 tion is based, he is met with absolute chaos. Not only is 
 this chaos present in the legislative enactments, it is also 
 only too evident in judicial decisions. Now, we could 
 perhaps excuse the legislatures for this deficiency, for as 
 our state legislatures are now composed, it is hardly to be 
 expected that they will have any continuous policy of legis- 
 lation in any branch of state activity ; and, in respect to the 
 labor law, they respond to the demands of their constitu- 
 ents just in proportion as the proposed measure seems a 
 good vote-getting device. But the courts which exercise 
 a great influence upon all social legislation through their 
 power to declare laws unconstitutional have no such excuse. 
 They have endeavored in some cases to throw the blame 
 for reactionary decisions upon the counsel who argued be- 
 fore them,^ but this excuse — to use their own language — 
 though perhaps evidence of extenuating circumstances does 
 not detract from the weight of the ofifense. 
 
 When I say that neither the courts nor the legislature act 
 upon any consistent philosophy of labor legislation, I am, in 
 one sense, not speaking with strict accuracy. The legislatures 
 do still act as they always have acted upon the theory that 
 laws which are strenuously demanded by a great number 
 are desirable, and the courts have formulated a maxim that 
 legislation must be for the welfare of the general public and 
 not of a particular class. Neither of these principles, how- 
 ever, is specific enough as a basis for legislation. More 
 concretely the courts from time to time have acted upon the 
 principle that those labor laws are proper which tend to 
 equalize the bargaining powers of labor and capital or upon 
 the principle that the legislature should only enact laws safe- 
 guarding the public health, morals or safety ; but neither of 
 these principles has been iterated consistently enough to be 
 called a philosophy of the courts. There is, then, in labor 
 legislation only the philosophic principle of individuahsm 
 
 N^Y^L^T*^^?^^ ^' ^^^™^"' ^44 111. 509; People v. Schweinler, S3
 
 293] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I47 
 
 dating back to Jeremy Bentham as modified by present con- 
 ditions in the direction of state intervention. But when it 
 is remembered that the exceptions to the individualistic 
 principles are more numerous than the rule, that the tend- 
 ency is towards state intervention and away from laissez- 
 faire, it will be obvious that some limitation upon state 
 action is necessary unless individualism is gradually to 
 change to socialism. There has as yet been formulated by 
 legislature or court no such limiting principle and the result 
 is a confused and chaotic mass of labor laws obeying no 
 definite rule of the relation of the state to labor. 
 
 In attempting to outline any system of philosophy of labor 
 legislation, we must, to conserve energy, use as many prin- 
 ciples of existing theories or systems as is possible. Not 
 only does such a plan conserve energy, but it also commends 
 itself in lending greater plausibility to the new scheme. 
 Before outlining our scheme, therefore, it will be necessary 
 to extract the best points from the two prevalent philoso- 
 phies of state activity, laissez-faire and socialism. 
 
 Laissez-faire, as has been said, is the philosophy of com- 
 plete inactivity on the part of the state. Realizing the value 
 of individual initiative, the believers in laissez-faire advo- 
 cated the absolutely unrestricted development of this vir- 
 tue. So sure were they of the efficacy of this quality that 
 they were content to conceive the welfare of the state as 
 merely the sum total of the welfare of the individuals 
 composing it. Now the philosophy of individualism is 
 sound in so far as it accentuates the necessity of individual 
 initiative and this is the element which we must try to 
 preserve; but experience soon proved that its corollary of 
 laissez-faire was an impossible solution of the relation of 
 the state to labor. Laissez-faire exalted competition with a 
 hope of weeding out the unfit, but the result was a compe- 
 tition between classes which must function together if they 
 are to attain the greatest common good. Instead of com- 
 petition weeding out the unfit and raising the standards of 
 social and industrial life, unregulated competition lowered
 
 148 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [294 
 
 the standards to the basis of those of the lowest competitor. 
 Not only did the individual suffer, but the community and 
 the state were also hurt by this rampant selfishness. And 
 the state suffers both from the individual suffering of its 
 citizens and from the torpidity v^hich this philosophy forces 
 upon it. Individual initiative should be fostered, but selfish- 
 ness must be carefully repressed. 
 
 As a reaction against this theory of the relation of the 
 state to its citizen, there came into being the political phi- 
 losophy of socialism. This philosophy, as I view it — and 
 there are almost as many views of socialism as there are 
 socialists — is the result of the theory that thinking men 
 "no longer hope for salvation through 'the free play of 
 individual interests,' and * freedom of contract ' . . . they 
 are apt to identify the cause of liberty with a policy of 
 social injustice. . , . The real test of liberty is to be found 
 less in the form of government or in the number of laws 
 that control the action of the citizen than in the extent to 
 which the citizen is assured the means of self-realization."' 
 So far again we may accept the tenets of this theory, but 
 the complete socialistic program of state activity goes on 
 to advocate at the least the socializatfon of all the means of 
 production. That is, socialism in opposition to laissez-faire 
 believes in the most intimate intervention of the state in the 
 life of its citizens, intervention extending as far as state 
 control, if not ownership, of all the factories, land, trans- 
 portation, and other productive agencies. Socialism by the 
 logical development of its fundamental tenet departs quite 
 as completely as does individualism from its original con- 
 cept. Socialism in endeavoring to assure to the citizen the 
 means of self-realization by a complete system of liberty- 
 making restrictions ends by completely stifling individual 
 initiative. This in the last analysis is the real argument 
 against socialism; it involves the rule of a bureaucracy in 
 political and industrial affairs, a superabundance of laws 
 which inevitably tend to deteriorate in quality as they in- 
 
 2 W. Jethro Brown, Underlying Principles of Legislation, p. 57 ff.
 
 295] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I49 
 
 crease in quantity, and a too frequent interference of the 
 administrative powers of the state in the life of the citizen 
 — all this at the expense of a proper encouragement of the 
 vitally necessary individual initiative. If a socialism could 
 be conceived which would preserve this one quality, it would 
 be desirable in spite of its other faults ; but so far no such 
 conception has been formulated. 
 
 We can then begin our constructive philosophy upon 
 these two fundamental ideas which have now received 
 rather general acceptance, the ideas that individual initia- 
 tive and self-realization must be stimulated and that a 
 proper use of legislation can be made to contribute to this 
 end. Individual initiative is essential to progress, but in- 
 dividualism untempered by state interference is an im- 
 possible principle. The state must interfere when individ- 
 ualism fails to achieve the greatest common good ; but the 
 state should interfere as rarely as possible, state interven- 
 tion should be always the secondary consideration. As 
 Schaffle says of the need of state intervention in the protec- 
 tion of labor: "It [the state] only steps in when self-help 
 and mutual help, supplemented by ordinary state protec- 
 tion, fail to meet the exigencies of the situation, whether 
 momentarily and on account of special circumstances, or by 
 the necessities of the case."^ The state's policy of inter- 
 vention should be not only temperate, but as far as pos- 
 sible uniform. That is, the state should not manifest itself 
 too variously in dififerentiated classes of laws, but should 
 strive to specialize its activity. One of the causes of the 
 failure of socialism is that the state is called upon to at- 
 tempt duties too diversified. The state promotes individual 
 initiative most effectively by confining itself as nearly as 
 possible to its prime duty of policing, and all its activity 
 should be closely related to this fundamental activity. Its 
 legislation to make real the theoretical liberty which the 
 laissez-faire philosophers believed in should be legislation 
 which really makes the individual capable of caring for him- 
 
 3 Schaffle, Labor Protection, p. 11.
 
 I 50 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [296 
 
 self, not legislation which attempts to take care of the 
 individual. 
 
 With these fundamental principles in mind, let us con- 
 sider the existing labor conditions. We have traced in the 
 first chapter the varying development of the theories of 
 labor l^w and it was pointed out that not until the last 
 period of this development, the period of laissez-faire miti- 
 gated by legislation in favor of the laborer, was the labor 
 problem serious enough to merit activity upon the part of 
 the state purely in solution of this problem. Moreover, it 
 was there also shown that this last period dated from soon 
 after the Industrial Revolution. These two facts are not 
 chance concomitants ; they have a real relation to the prob- 
 lem. Prior to the Industrial Revolution, the employer and 
 employee were in intimate personal relation to each other. 
 The employer employed few men and usually did part of 
 the manual labor himself. He usually knew the conditions 
 of these men and took an interest in their welfare. More- 
 over, the men were able to bargain successfully for their 
 own welfare, for the employee had almost as many shops 
 in which to seek employment as the employers had occa- 
 sions to employ workmen. In other words, the business 
 unit was so small that the individual employer had no 
 greater monopoly of jobs than the employee had of work- 
 ing ability. After the Industrial Revolution, however, one 
 employer employed hundreds and thousands of workmen. 
 Not only did he have greater experience in hiring labor 
 than the employee had in seeking work, but because of the 
 magnitude of his business he had more of a monopoly of 
 the jobs obtainable. Briefly, the employer had what the 
 employee wanted most of all — work; he usually was not 
 hard put to it to get what the employee had — labor ; he was 
 in a superior economic position and had more experience in 
 making the contract of employment. The individual em- 
 ployee was practically at the mercy of the employer; the 
 employer set the conditions of employment and the em- 
 ployee was compelled to acquiesce in them.
 
 297] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I5I 
 
 As an offset to this inequality of bargaining power, the 
 workman evolved the old craft gild into the labor union. 
 By thus combining the individuals in a particular craft into 
 an organized whole and developing one of the members into 
 a trained bargainer, the employees were able to balance the 
 monopoly and the experience of the employer. Collective 
 bargaining for the whole union was substituted for the in- 
 dividual bargaining of the single employee. But this solu- 
 tion has not been adequate. It was because unionism was 
 incomplete, however, not because it was ineffective, that 
 the state was compelled to legislate. The state soon discov- 
 ered that it had to interfere in the labor contract ; absolute 
 laissez-faire was not feasible under a factory system of in- 
 dustry and an unorganized community of laborers. The 
 more powerful employer, it was found, used his power 
 selfishly to the detriment of the state. The state recognized 
 the inequality of the bargaining power of the two parties 
 to the contract and stepped in to remedy the effects of this 
 inequality. Would it not have been better to have reme- 
 died the inequality? If the state, instead of establishing 
 certain of the terms of the labor contract, had made the 
 employee capable of establishing these terms for himself, 
 its task would have been much simplified. If the state had 
 legislated to make equal the bargaining power of the two 
 parties, if the state had legislated to encourage the devel- 
 opment of collective bargaining, it would have effected per- 
 haps, not a panacea, but a much greater reform than any 
 law so far has effected. A really strong labor imion as a 
 means of collective bargaining would render unnecessary 
 much of the ever-increasing bulk of social legislation. To 
 achieve unionism should be the first aim of state activity. 
 
 Experience sustains this conclusion. The well-organized 
 — I might even say the organized — labor union asks little 
 of the state except legal recognition and the absence of 
 legal persecution. It is perfectly reliant upon its own pow- 
 ers. Through its control of labor and its own resources, it 
 is enabled to withstand the natural ascendancy of the em-
 
 1^2 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [298 
 
 ployer and bargain through its trained agents for its fair 
 share of the product. It is within the scope of the union's 
 power to bargain as to hours of labor, wages, days of rest, 
 conditions of apprenticeship, etc. The trade union as a 
 fraternal organization can provide for out-of-work bene- 
 fits, sickness insurance, old-age pensions, and the like. 
 What is more important, the labor union can better care 
 for the terms of the employment of its members through 
 its bargaining with the employer than the state could 
 through legislative enactment, for the labor union can bet- 
 ter recognize the local and incidental variations of each 
 trade and better provide for them in its terms than could 
 the state. Thus the English textile workers in conjunction 
 with the employers maintain expensive experts to arrange 
 sliding scales of wages and hours to conform to various 
 conditions and to fix new terms when new conditions ar- 
 rive.'* And, furthermore, with respect to the benefits, the 
 union is able to provide more efficient administration than 
 the state could because of its more intimate connection with 
 the recipients of the premiums. Together with the strength 
 and numbers of the central and federal unions, these or- 
 ganizations provide a much subdivided and minutely classi- 
 fied administrative device for the amelioration of labor 
 conditions. This must be considered an additional argu- 
 ment for the policy of noninterference, which indeed 
 weighs very heavily in conjunction with individualistic 
 reasoning. In these fields which have just been discussed 
 the labor union can be perfectly efficient, but in order to 
 be efficient, it must contain practically every worker in its 
 trade, perhaps an entirely impracticable condition. 
 
 The labor union, however, even in its strongest condition 
 is not able entirely to replace the state in looking after the 
 welfare of the laborer. Certain laws must still be enacted. 
 The state must, of course, legislate with reference to the 
 labor union itself. The union naturally must be legalized 
 
 4 See Webb, Industrial Democracy, for a description of this 
 scneme and for an appreciation of its workings toward amicable 
 relations between labor and capital.
 
 299] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR 153 
 
 and, as will be seen, aided in some manner before it can 
 begin its function as efficient competitive bargainer, for the 
 common law, especially as affected by early English labor 
 legislation, is not friendly to labor unions. In other re- 
 spects, also, amendment of the common law will be neces- 
 sary to conform this inelastic system to changing industrial 
 conditions. The workmen's compensation movement is a 
 present instance of this branch of state activity. The labor 
 imion could inaugurate schemes of accident insurance and 
 some unions have done so; but under the common law of 
 master and servant a scheme of accident insurance would, 
 in a great majority of industries, become most expensive. 
 The state alone can abrogate the doctrine of assumption of 
 risk and fellow-servant negligence and ameliorate or abro- 
 gate the theory of contributory negligence. Most impor- 
 tant is it that the labor union should bargain for and help to 
 regulate the conditions and environment of employment. 
 Certain minor provisions, of course, the unions will always 
 stipulate for, but conditions of sanitation, fire-prevention, 
 and safety appliances are beyond the scope of their powers. 
 In the framing and enforcement of such provisions expert 
 knowledge beyond the reach of unions is necessary; and, 
 moreover, in the fundamentals, a uniformity must exist 
 which higgling and bargaining from their nature never 
 can procure. Within these three rubrics, then, the legali- 
 zation of the union, the correction of the common law, 
 and the regulation of the conditions of labor, the activity 
 of the state should b6 contained ; beyond them is the sphere 
 in which the state should act only in aid of the union and 
 in furtherance of its schemes. In this way, as I see it, 
 could individual initiative be encouraged and the state care 
 best for the general welfare. This, in other words, is an 
 ideal system of state activity. 
 
 Accepting provisionally this assumption, the possibility 
 of which will be later demonstrated, that labor is fully 
 organized, that indeed each union has a practical monopoly 
 of the workmen in its trade, the question presents itself :
 
 154 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [3OO 
 
 Will the unions become so strong when they have once 
 been brought into power that they will not only control the 
 capitalists and become the first claimants in distribution, 
 but that they will set up a kind of inverted autocracy in 
 which the union leaders represent their class to the entire 
 emancipation of the capitalists ? Such a result seems some- 
 what fantastic, but the recognition of its probability leads 
 to profitable speculation. 
 
 In the first place, even assuming that the great propor- 
 tion of laborers are unionists, the place of capital in the 
 economic and social system would still be an important 
 one; and, unless communism followed unionism — and this 
 does not seem probable or even logical — the class of capi- 
 talists would be separate from and necessary to the work- 
 ingmen. Moreover, when unionism is at its highest point, 
 from one-third to one-half of the working population, farm 
 laborers, professional men, and the like, are engaged in 
 pursuits in which unionization is impossible or tmnecessary. 
 And it must be remembered that the unorganized portion 
 of the population will still include the professions, the 
 brains of the country. But, in all this discussion, that 
 which must struggle for completion is recognized as in full 
 bloom before any resistance or restriction is organized. Of 
 course, this is inconceivable. With the advent of fully 
 organized labor, there will develop organizations of em- 
 ployers after the nature of the present employers' associa- 
 tions to combat the rising menace to their profits. No gov- 
 ernment aid will be needed to help them into existence and 
 the law will hardly antagonize them as imion combatants 
 so long as they restrict themselves to agreements concern- 
 ing labor. These employers' associations will also approach 
 to a monopoly, a monopoly of jobs, and there will be then 
 on opposite sides two aggressive organizations, each seek- 
 ing for its members the larger share in distribution. A 
 battle under those circumstances is inconceivable. On be- 
 half of the consuming public, the state would step in to 
 effect control over those large labor questions whose inci-
 
 30l] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I 5$ 
 
 dental variations it had left to the labor union. In other 
 words, some form of mediation, arbitration or conciliation 
 is necessary. 
 
 It is out of place here to enter into any detailed discus- 
 sion of the modes of amicable settlement of labor disputes. 
 The plan called for here is some kind of a government 
 commission with the powers of one of the present minimum 
 wage commissions to settle all questions of terms of em- 
 ployment which the agents of the labor union and employ- 
 ers' association cannot agree upon. The necessity of ap- 
 pealing to this commission and accepting its awards may, 
 if necessary, be made compulsory and binding upon the 
 acceptance of government aid by the unions. Constitu- 
 tional objections will be raised, but we must sometimes 
 remember that the constitutions are not the last word in 
 social legislation and social readjustment. 
 
 There are, however, certain practical questions which 
 have been slurred over in the previous discussion, but which 
 must now be considered in all their glaring baldness. It is, 
 indeed, one of the drawbacks of philosophizing and theoriz- 
 ing that practicalities always constrain one to justify his 
 theories. Perhaps that is why there is such a paucity of 
 theories in the world and so many "practical men." 
 
 In the first place, then, it has been assumed that, in order 
 to guarantee to the state its proper place in the amelioration 
 of social conditions, labor has become completely organized. 
 " The success of a union in enforcing its demands depends 
 upon the extent to which it has control over the labor sup- 
 ply in its particular occupation, since, if an employer is 
 easily able to fill the places of those on strike, it is evident 
 that the whole movement fails in its purpose."^ It has 
 been calculated, however, that only between five and six 
 per cent of the workers of the country are organized, and 
 that few unions control half the laborers in their crafts." 
 
 5 Weyf orth, " Organizability of Labor," in Johns Hopkins Uni- 
 versity Studies, ser. xxxv, no. 2, p. 146. Much of the following has 
 been suggested by this monograph. 
 
 ^ Wolman, Extent of Organization in the United States, MS.
 
 1^6 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [302 
 
 These figures, however, exaggerate the problem confront- 
 ing us, though they do suggest its magnitude and, perhaps, 
 the fancifulness of the project. One of the greatest diffi- 
 culties in the way of organizing laborers is the opposition 
 of the employers to unionization. This is a natural phe- 
 nomenon of competition, but it seems a passing one. Its 
 most destructive opponents are public opinion and the 
 growing consciousness among employers that it is to the 
 benefit of each employer to have all the workers in his 
 trade organized. For only then is the employer sure that 
 his competitor is not undercutting with cheap labor, and 
 his care is to obtain relative, not absolute, cheapness in the 
 elements of his product. This problem, however, will find 
 its own cure; legislation in its nature follows as well as 
 develops public opinion. The country when willing to ac- 
 cept the scheme of legislation here set forth will present a 
 concerted opinion strong enough to offset the opposition of 
 the employers to unionization. 
 
 A more serious problem confronting the organizer of 
 labor, from the point of view of this study, is the apathy 
 of the laborers. This manifests itself in two forms, in the 
 apathy of the individual worker in an organized trade and 
 in the apathy of a whole trade resulting from the nature 
 of the trade. The indifferent worker is a problem for 
 modern unionism which the unions of today are fast learn- 
 ing to handle successfully; but, in the eyes of a scheme 
 which would only succeed through a general appreciation 
 of the union as the natural, fixed economic phenomenon 
 which it seems to be, this problem sinks into insignificance. 
 The really serious difficulty is the apathetic trade, the trade 
 which seems impervious to organization. The unskilled, 
 floating workers because of their great number and the 
 aimlessness of their interest, the women in employment 
 because of the transitoriness of their employment and be- 
 cause they look to marriage rather than wages as a means 
 of livelihood, and the home-workers because the scattered 
 condition of the employment makes enforcement of union
 
 303] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR 1 57 
 
 regulations well-nigh impossible are the black sheep of labor 
 unionism. That a stimulating impulse is the necessity in 
 the case of the unskilled and the women, that these classes 
 are not impossible, but merely difficult to organize, is dem- 
 onstrated by the success of such unions as the stevedores 
 and hodcarriers and of the New York garment workers' 
 protocol. The home-workers, if the law is content that 
 there be home-workers, seem conclusively without the field 
 of unionism. The isolated conditions of employment, the 
 private nature of their occupation, make impossible such 
 union regulations as an eight hour day, standard wages or 
 a closed shop. But this is not fatal to the argument that 
 the unions should regulate the terms of employment, for 
 the same conditions would make equally impossible an effi- 
 cient state regulation of these terms. Except as to the 
 conditions of the environment of employment, which under 
 any scheme of social legislation must come under state con- 
 trol, the home-workers are incapable of outside regulation. 
 
 Another class of workers who are not well organized are 
 those who labor in small one-man industries. These in- 
 clude farm laborers, domestic servants, workmen in small 
 country shops, and the workers in the so-called one-man 
 shop. The organizing condition of these employments is 
 analagous to that of the home-workers, but it is not abso- 
 lutely incompatible with organization, as is evidenced by 
 unions of barbers and the like. The labor problem, how- 
 ever, in these industries is not so acute as in the larger 
 centralized employments, for the laborer is in intimate rela- 
 tion with his employer. In fact, these occupations are quite 
 of the nature of the early forms of industry when no labor 
 legislation was enacted, and even today these occupations 
 are often omitted from labor legislation. Instead of en- 
 hancing, these workers may be said to mitigate our problem. 
 
 The problem then is, if it is desirable to make the great- 
 est possible use of labor unions in the amelioration of labor 
 conditions and if it is desirable to establish a limit to state 
 intervention where the concerted action of the workingmen
 
 158 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [3O4 
 
 shall work out their own salvation, — the problem then is to 
 secure almost complete organization among laborers. Be- 
 cause of the antipathy of the employers and the apathy of 
 some laborers, as explained, the organizability of labor 
 seems to stand at a rather low level. Public opinion, it is 
 true, plays a large part in determining the level at which 
 the labor barometer stands, but public opinion cannot over- 
 come all the obstacles in the way of labor organization. 
 Active help must be furnished from the outside. It is here 
 that the state may bargain for the controlling interest in the 
 manipulation of trade union affairs which is necessary to 
 amicable settlement of industrial disputes. Two modes of 
 state aid will illustrate the kind of help necessary and the 
 problems involved, but the exposition of these two schemes 
 must not be accepted as exhaustive of the methods of state 
 aid. 
 
 The first plan for state aid is in the nature of financial 
 encouragement. One of the main weapons of organization 
 is the beneficial system of trade union insurance. Not only 
 is this an effective lure to the conservative workman, but it 
 is one of the chief inducements to permanent organization 
 when the initial stimulus of a successful strike or boycott 
 has spent its constructive force. Two of the most impor- 
 tant of these benefits are out-of-work and sickness benefits. 
 The state could contribute to one of these and make the 
 union so much more eiTective by its aid.'' As a condition 
 of this contribution, the state could stipulate that through 
 
 ^The expense of this scheme would not be great. Taking as a 
 typical example of the source of state aid, the State of Maryland, a 
 fair estimate would be the addition of three and one-fifth cents to 
 the tax rate. This estimate is arrived at in the following manner: 
 The working population of Maryland is 541,164 (Census of 1910, 
 Vol. V, p. III). Deducting 222,247, the number of farm-hands, pro- 
 prietors and professional men, etc., the total number of organizable 
 workers at a generous estimate is 318,917. The average per capita 
 cost of out-of-work benefits in two unions, the Cigar Maker and 
 Typographic, from 1900 to 1905 was $3.55 (from tables in Kennedy, 
 Beneficiary Features of Trade Unions, p. 91). If the State should 
 contribute 30 per cent of this amount, again a most liberal estimate, 
 the total cost for Maryland would be $329,647 or 3.2 cents on the tax 
 assessment basis of 1914.
 
 305] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I §9 
 
 its commission or board of arbitration or some similar 
 board, it should have intimate control over the affairs of 
 the union. This scheme would have to meet the objections 
 against all state insurance schemes ; and it could meet them 
 rather effectively ; but none of these, because of the nature 
 of this discussion, is important to dwell upon except the 
 question of constitutionality, that bugaboo of all social 
 legislation. 
 
 Under existing state constitutions,® this method of state 
 aid would be illegal ; but most state constitutions are easily 
 and often amended so that the real difficulty lies in the 
 relatively staid Federal Constitution. The " due process of 
 law " clause interpreted as forbidding state taxation for 
 private purposes and the " equal protection of the law " 
 clause of the Fourteenth Amendment as usual raise their 
 threatening forms in the path of this legislation. In the 
 first place, would such a system of state contribution to 
 union benefits involve taxation for a private purpose? 
 
 The first ground upon which this legislation would be 
 sought to be upheld would naturally be as an extension of 
 the proper state function of poor relief, for, in taxation 
 cases, the courts lend most weight to the historical argu- 
 ment. It might be argued that, inasmuch as the State may 
 relieve its poverty-stricken citizens, it should be enabled 
 to grant aid as a preventative of those conditions. Now 
 the two kinds of contributions, of which one is advocated, 
 are both directed against prime causes of poverty, the sick- 
 ness or unemployment of the wage-earner of the family. 
 The argument is perfectly sound that an ounce of preven- 
 tion is worth a pound of cure, but the majority of the 
 courts of the country have refused to be guided by this 
 proverb.® State relief, it has been generally held, can only 
 be granted to those absolutely indigent. At least one court, 
 
 ^See, e. g., the Maryland Constitution, Art. Ill, Sec. 34: "The 
 credit of the State shall not in any manner be given ... in aid of 
 any individual association or corporation." 
 
 ^ See Goodnow, Social Reform and the Constitution, chap. 7, and 
 cases there cited.
 
 l60 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [306 
 
 however, has taken the logical, if not the historical and 
 legal, position just set forth and has upheld a preventative 
 measure;^" but, except as an entering wedge, this opinion 
 lends little encouragement because of its uniqueness. 
 
 Driven from this ground by the conservatism of the 
 courts, it is more profitable to consider whether the State 
 is not obtaining for itself by indirect means a perfectly valid 
 advantage. " It is obvious that what is a public use fre- 
 quently and largely depends upon the facts and circum- 
 stances surrounding the particular subject matter in regard 
 to which the character of the use is questioned."^^ It is 
 useless to quote cases. The irreconcilable differences of 
 the opinions makes it possible to quote in favor of either 
 position. Let us then appeal to reason. By making the 
 nominal expenditure for beneficiary payments, the State 
 saves itself the cost of expensive commissions and experts 
 necessary for the efficient administration of this part of 
 the labor law, saves its legislators endless trouble by ren- 
 dering unnecessary a great multitude of enactments, and 
 exercises an interest of utmost impwDrtance in maintaining 
 amicable relations between employers and employees, in 
 preventing labor wars. The state takes this means of legis- 
 lating with respect to the fundamentals of the labor ques- 
 tion instead of striving to correct the deformity of modern 
 industrial life by attacking merely the symptoms and out- 
 growths of the inequalities now existing between labor and 
 capital. The State, it would seem, has a right to legislate 
 in this manner and "it is established by a series of cases 
 that an ulterior public advantage may justify a compara- 
 tively insignificant taking of private property for what, in 
 its immediate purpose, is a private use."^^ 
 
 This line of reasoning also makes unnecessary any ex- 
 tended reference to the "equal protection of the law" 
 clause. All unions and unionists will receive similar aid 
 
 10 North Dakota v. Nelson Co., i N. D. 88. 
 
 ^1 Fallbrook Irrigation District v. Bradley, 164 U. S. 112. 
 
 ^2 Noble State Bank v. Haskell, 219 U. S. 104, and cases cited.
 
 307] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR I6I 
 
 from the government, and everybody will be able to secure 
 this aid by entering a union, for, in fact, to secure complete 
 organizations is the prime motive of the aid. The unions, 
 through governmental insistence, must hold themselves open 
 to receive any worker having the qualifications of the trade ; 
 and the State must stand ready to extend its aid to all 
 unions coming into existence. All who unionize receive 
 government assistance and those who refuse to organize 
 have themselves to blame. The discrimination between 
 unionists and non-unionists, in reality, amounts to very little, 
 and this discrimination is justified by the end to be attained. 
 
 As a second mode of state encouragement to organiza- 
 tion, a scheme lending actual assistance to the establish- 
 ment of a preferential union shop in the several industries 
 is suggested. Little argument is necessary to prove that 
 if actual preference is given to the man bearing union cre- 
 dentials in obtaining the open job, great advantage is given 
 to the union. It would, perhaps, be too difficult to attempt 
 to absolutely enforce a closed shop or even a preferential 
 shop by legal enactment, but any aid in this direction would 
 be beneficial, and perhaps sufficiently beneficial to stimulate 
 organization among the apathetic workers, certainly bene- 
 ficial as a weapon against the antipathetic employers. It is 
 not necessary to suggest a typical law, but it would be in- 
 teresting to consider the constitutionality of a law similar 
 to that which has been passed in several States penalizing 
 the discharge of a workingman because of his membership 
 in a union or penalizing an employer for insisting upon an 
 agreement from the worker not to join a union during his 
 employment, either of which would be enforced only as to 
 unions submitting to government intervention in their deal- 
 ings with the employers. 
 
 At first glance, either of these laws would seem clearly 
 unconstitutional under decisions of the Supreme Court in 
 the Adair^' and Coppage cases ;^* but there is one new 
 
 "Adair v. United States, 208 U. S. 161. 
 1* Coppage V. Kansas, 236 U. S. i.
 
 1 62 THE LABOR LAW OF MARYLAND [308 
 
 feature, government control, introduced which will at least 
 weigh in the direction of constitutionality, and, moreover, 
 it is most deferentially submitted, the decisions in these two 
 cases are open to criticism. Both of the majority opinions 
 in these cases were written by the conservative, if not the 
 reactionary, justice of the bench and both of them are rea- 
 soned out upon eighteenth century notions of the inviola- 
 bility of natural rights. The Court does not take judicial 
 cognizance of twentieth century conditions as affecting 
 these eighteenth century rights. It lays aside as immaterial 
 the practical inequality of the employer and the unorgan- 
 ized worker and sees no possibility of coercion in the mu- 
 tual employment agreements. " But in view of the relative 
 positions of employer and employed," asks Justice Day in 
 his dissenting opinion in the later case, " who is to deny 
 that the stipulation [not to enter a union during employ- 
 mient] here insisted upon and forbidden by law is essentially 
 coercive?" It is useless to attack at any greater length 
 these decisions ; the dissenting opinions are stronger than 
 anything else which could be written. The proposed laws, 
 however, can be held constitutional in spite of these two 
 cases. Not only would the State be attempting to aid the 
 unions by the&e laws, it wotdd be fulfilling a purpose of its 
 own in the amelioration of inequitable labor conditions and 
 in the amicable adjustment of labor disputes. The unions 
 would take on the nature of public institutions; and, as 
 the Court says in the Coppage case, "if they were, a differ- 
 ent question would be presented " than the one there con- 
 sidered. 
 
 These two methods of state aid are, then, illustrative of 
 the kind of legislation needed to consummate the idealized 
 condition of affairs herein assumed. To encourage indi- 
 vidual initiative and to repress selfishness in a proper pro- 
 portion, so that both the individual and the community 
 may prosper, the State's first duty in labor legislation is to 
 stimulate unionization. Until complete unionization is at- 
 tained, the State may hav€ to legislate in fields beyond
 
 309] THE STATE IN RELATION TO LABOR 1 63 
 
 those to which this system would limit it; and in those 
 fields the previous chapters of this study have sought to 
 lay down sound standards of legislation. When, however, 
 unionization is once complete and with it have come into 
 existence the employers' associations, the State will be able 
 to leave most of the terms of the labor contract to the two 
 parties, itself intervening through the agency of the gov- 
 ernmental commission only on the rare occasions when the 
 public welfare seems at stake. The only other care of the 
 State will be to keep the unwritten law up to date and to 
 legislate concerning safety and sanitary conditions. Per- 
 haps this outline seems too ideal, but in that it is like all 
 logical philosophies — when they become constructive they 
 necessarily go to extremes and extremes are not reason- 
 able ; only the mean is reasonable and that is not logical.
 
 INDEX 
 
 Accident. See Workmen's Com- 
 pensation Law. 
 
 Accident Fund, 65-66. 
 
 Administration of labor law, 
 122 fi. 
 
 Apprentices, statute of, 11. 
 
 Arbitration, compulsory and vol- 
 untary, 41 flf. ; publicity method 
 of, 42. 
 
 Assumption of risk, 53, 71 
 
 Attachments and liens, 116 ff. 
 
 Barnett, G. E., 47 (note). 
 Bentham, Jeremy, 147. 
 Black-list, uses of, 33-35, 108, 
 
 114. 
 Board for Mothers' Relief for 
 
 Baltimore City, 119. 
 Boycott, 22, 25 ; secondary, 24, 
 
 25, . 29-30 ; primary, 29-30 ; 
 
 distinction between primary 
 
 and secondary, 30-32. 
 Brandeis, L. D., loi (note). 
 Brown, W. Jethro, 148 (note). 
 Bryan, J. W., 20 (note). 
 Bureau of Industrial Statistics 
 
 and Inspection, 87, 98 
 Bureau of Statistics and Infor- 
 mation, 43-44, 123, 136. 
 
 Canneries, 102. 
 
 Child Labor Law, 99, loi, 126, 
 
 130-131. 
 Child welfare, 117, 119, 132. 
 Civil service reform, 136 ff. 
 Closed shop, 22, 25 ; methods of, 
 
 3<^38. 
 Colfhing Cutters' Assembly, 25. 
 Commission, proposed, 77 ff. 
 Common law, relation to labor 
 
 law, lo-ii; of contracts, 37; 
 
 in relation to compensation 
 
 law, 75. 
 Commons, J. R., 78 (note), 79. 
 Compensation. See Workmen's 
 
 Compensation Law. 
 Conciliation, 41-45. 
 Conspiracy, law of, 19, 20. 
 
 Constitutional provisions in 
 United States, relation of, to 
 labor law, 13-14. 
 
 Contract, freedom of, 22. 
 
 Contributory negligence, 53, 71, 
 
 153. 
 Cooperative Insurance Fund, 46- 
 
 48. 
 Course of employment, 63 ff. 
 
 Disability, compensation for, 
 
 S8ff. 
 Discharge of employees, 35. 
 "Due process of law" clause, 14, 
 
 153. 
 
 Employers' Associations, 154, 
 
 Employers' Liability Case, 71. 
 
 Employment, conditions of, 76 
 ff. ; terms of, 94 ff. ; prohibi- 
 tions of, 96 ff. See hours of 
 labor, sanitation, fire protec- 
 tion, etc. 
 
 Employment, in course of, 63 ff. 
 
 Employment agencies, 126. 
 
 Equal protection, 159, 160. 
 
 Factory inspection and indus- 
 trial registration law, 126 ff. 
 Fellow servant negligence, 53, 
 
 71, 153. 
 Fire protection and suggested 
 
 measures, 81-85. 
 Fourteenth Amendment, 14, 41 ; 
 
 " equal protection of the law " 
 
 clause of, 159, 160. 
 Freund, Ernst, 48 (note), 55 
 
 (note). 
 
 Goodnow, F. J., 129 (note). 
 
 Harlan, H. D., 74 (note). 
 Health, State Board of, 89-90, 
 
 123, 133-135- 
 Herkner, Anna, 83 (note). 
 Holmes, Justice, 14, 36, 71. 
 Home-work, 90-93. 
 
 164
 
 3iO 
 
 INDEX 
 
 165 
 
 Hours of labor, for women and 
 children, 100-103, 126, 13a; 
 for men, 103-104. 
 
 Industrial Accident Commis- 
 sion, State, 65, 67-70, 85, 123, 
 
 135. 
 
 Injunctions, 30. 
 
 Insurance, 158-161. See Work- 
 men's Compensation Law. 
 
 Interlocking directorates, no. 
 
 Label, union, 39-41. 
 
 Labor, disputes, settlement of, 
 
 155. 
 
 Labor, State in relation to, 145 flf. 
 
 Labor and Statistics, State 
 Board of, 44, 87, 91-92, 123 ff. 
 
 Labor Day, 121. 
 
 Labor Department, need of 
 Maryland for, 139 ff . 
 
 Labor law, definition of, 9; dif- 
 ferentiation of, from common 
 law, 10 ; character of early, n- 
 12, 20. 
 
 Labor union, 19 flf. 
 
 Laborers, Statute of, il. 
 
 Laissez-faire, relation of doc- 
 trine to labor law, 11-12, ^^, 
 
 147. 
 
 Leiserson, W. M., 126 (note). 
 
 Liability, employers. See Work- 
 men's Compensation Law. 
 
 License laws, 113 flf., 115-116. 
 
 Liens, 116. 
 
 Living wage, 105. 
 
 Lucke V. Clothing Cutters' As- 
 sembly, 25. 
 
 Luman v. Kitchens, in. 
 
 Malice, 22. 
 
 Martin, W, A., 23 (note), 40 
 (note). 
 
 Maryland Court of Appeals, 14; 
 on criminal conspiracy, 20. 
 
 Maryland Labor law, compara- 
 tively considered, 16-17; his- 
 torically considered, 19-20 ; ad- 
 ministrative system of, 122 
 ff. ; suggestions for reforms 
 in, 136 ff. 
 
 Mechanics' liens, 116 flf. 
 
 Minimum wage law, 104-106. 
 
 Mothers' pensions, 118. 
 
 My Maryland Lodge v. Adt, 23- 
 24, 28, 30. 
 
 Negligence, contributory, 53, 71, 
 153- 
 
 Occupational diseases, 64. 
 
 Picketing, 25, 27-29. 
 
 Pickett v. Walsh, 26. 
 
 Police power, 72. 
 
 Public employment, terms of, 
 
 1 19-120. 
 Pure Food and Drugs Act, 134. 
 
 Relief fund, 49. 
 Restraint of trade, 37. 
 Risk, assumption of, 53, Ti. 
 Rubinow, J. M., 53 (note). 
 
 Safety and sanitary measures, 
 
 8sff. 
 Sanitary Inspection Law, 89-90, 
 
 133-135. 
 
 Sanitation, 86, 129. See Health, 
 State Board of. 
 
 Schaflfle, A., 149. 
 
 School attendance, 118. 
 
 Second Employers' Liability 
 Case, 71. 
 
 Shaffer v. Union Mining Com- 
 pany, no. 
 
 Socialism, 148-149, 150. 
 
 State Accident Fund, 65-66. 
 
 State aid to trade unions, in- 
 surance, 158-161 ; preferential 
 union shop, 161 ; constitution- 
 ality of, 161-162. 
 
 State Board of Health, 89-90, 
 
 123, 133-135- , ^ 
 
 State Board of Labor and Sta- 
 tistics, 44, 87, 91-92; adminis- 
 tration and duties of, 123 ff. 
 
 State employment, 119 ff. 
 
 State Industrial Accident Com- 
 mission, 65, 67-70, 85, 123, 135. 
 
 State v. Potomac Coal Com- 
 pany, III. 
 
 Statute of Apprentices, Eliza- 
 bethan, II. 
 
 Statute of Laborers, 11. 
 
 Strike, object of, 22 ff., 38; sym- 
 pathetic, 24; when legal in- 
 strument, 24. 
 
 Sunday Rest Law, 121. 
 
 Supreme Court, on discharge of 
 union employees, 35. 
 
 Sympathetic strike, 24.
 
 I 66 INDEX [312 
 
 Tenement law, 90-93. Wages of labor, 104 ff. 
 
 Tort, law of, 74- "Waiting period," 61. 
 
 Trade union, development of Webb, Sidney, 152 (note). 
 
 law of, in Maryland, 19-23; Weyforth, W. O., 155 (note). 
 
 statutes relating to, 39-41 ; Willner v. Silverman, 35. 
 
 aims of, 151-153; state aid to, Wolman, Leo, 155 (note). 
 
 158-161. Women's ten-hour law, 102, 126, 
 
 Truck system, 107 ff.; history 132. 
 
 of, in Maryland, 109 ff. Workmen's Compensation Law 
 
 Typographical Union, Interna- of Maryland, history of, 46 ff.; 
 
 tional, 41. compared with other similar 
 
 laws, 56 ff. ; constitutionality 
 
 Union label, 39-41. of, 70 ff.; effects on common 
 
 Union labor, 19 ff. law, 74, 125. 
 L'nion shop, 161.
 
 Johns Hopkins University Studies 
 
 in Historical and Political Science 
 
 The University Studies will continue to publish, as heretofore, 
 the results of recent investigations in History, Political Economy, 
 and Political Science. 
 
 The titles given below are now announced ; other numbers will 
 follow from time to time. 
 
 Unemployment and American Trade Unions. By D. P. Smklbkb, Jr. 
 $1.25 in paper; cloth, $1.50. 
 
 The Labor Law of Maryland. By M. H. Laugheimer. $1.25 in 
 paper; cloth, $1.50. 
 
 The American Colonization Society (1817-1840). By E. L. Fox. 
 The Japanese Judiciary. By T. Yokoyama. 
 
 The National Debt of Japan. By S. Kitasawa. 
 
 The cost of subscription for the regular annual series, comprising 
 about 600 pages, is $3.50. Single numbers, or special monographs, 
 at special prices. Complete contents of previous volumes are given 
 on pages viii-xii.
 
 STUDIES IN HISTORY, ECONOMICS 
 AND PUBLIC LAW 
 
 EDITED BY 
 
 THE FACULTY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE OF 
 
 COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY 
 
 RECENT NUMBERS 
 
 VOLUME LXXV. 1917. 410 pp. Price, cloth, $4.00. 
 An extra-illustrated and bound volume is published at S5.00. 
 
 1 [177] New York as an Eighteenth Century Municipality. Prior to 1731. 
 ' ' By Ar'xhur Everett Peterson, Ph.D. 
 
 2 [178] New York as an Eighteenth Century Municipality. 1731-1776. 
 
 By George William Edwards, Ph.D. 
 VOLUME LXXVI. 1917. 489 pp. Price, cloth, $4.00. 
 
 1 (1791 ♦Economic and Social History of Chowan County, North Carolina. 
 ■ ' ^ By W. Scott Boyce, Ph.D. 
 
 2 [180] Separation of State and Local Revenues in the United States. 
 
 By Mabel Newcomer, Ph.D. Price, $i.7S 
 
 VOLUME LXXVn. 1917. 473 pp. Price, cloth, $4.00. 
 [181] American Civil Church Law. By Carl Zollmann, LL.B. 
 
 VOLUME LXXVm. 1917. 647 pp. Price, cloth, $4.50. 
 [182] The Colonial Merchants and the American Revolution. 
 
 By Arthur Meier Schlesinger, Ph.D. 
 VOLUME LXXIX. 1917-1918. 535 pp. Price, cloth, $4.50. 
 
 1. [183] Contemporary Theories of Unemployment and Unemployment Relief. 
 
 By Frederick C. Mills, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [ 184] The French Assembly of 1848 and American Constitutional Doctrine. 
 
 By Eugene Newton Curtis, Ph.D. 
 VOLUME LXXX. 1918. 448 pp. Price, cloth, $4.00. 
 
 1. (185] *Valuation and Rate-making. By Robert L. Hale, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [186] The Enclosure of Open Fields in England. 
 
 By Harriet Bradley, Ph.D. 
 
 3. [187] The Land Tax in China. By H. L. Huang, Ph.D. 
 
 VOLUME LXXXI. 1918. 601 pp. Price, cloth, $4.50. 
 
 1. [188] Social Life in Rome in the Time of Plautus and Terence. 
 
 By Georgia W. Leffingwell, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [189] *Australian Social Development. 
 
 By Clarence H. Northcott, Ph.D. 
 
 3. [190] *Factory Statistics and Industrial Fatigue. 
 
 By Philip S. Florence, Ph.D. 
 VOLUME LXXXII. 1918-1919. 
 
 1. [191] New England and the Bavarian Uluminati. 
 
 By Vernon Stauffer, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [192] Resale Price Maintenance. By Claudius T. Murchison. {In Press.) 
 
 VOLUME LXXXUL 1919. 432 pp. Price, cloth, $4.00. 
 [193] The I. W. W. By Paul E. Brissenden, Ph.D. 
 
 VOLUME LXXXIV. 1919. 
 
 1. [194] The Royal Government of Virginia, 1634-1775. 
 
 By Percy Scott Flippin, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [195] (To be announced.) 
 
 VOLUME LXXXV. 1919. 
 
 1. [196] The Ecclesiastical Policy of Bavaria during the Napoleonic Period. 
 
 By Chester P. Higby, Ph.D. 
 
 2. [197] (To be announced.) 
 
 VOLUME LXXXVI. 1919. 
 [198] The Decline of Aristocracy in the Politics of New York. 
 
 By Dixon Ryan Fox, Ph.D. (.In Press.} 
 
 The prica for each separate monograph is for paper-covered copies; separate monographs 
 marked *, can be supplied in cloth for fifty cents additional. All prices are net. 
 
 The set of Eighty-one volumes, covering monographs 1-190, is offered bound for 
 
 S277, except that Vol. U can be supplied only in part and in paper covers, 
 
 No. 1 of that volume being out of print Volumes m, IV and XXV 
 
 can now be supplied only in connection with complete sets. 
 
 For further information apply to 
 
 MESSRS. LONGMANS, GREEN & CO., New York. 
 Londoa: P. S. KING & SON, Ltd., Orchard House, Westminster. 
 
 Price, $2.00. 
 Price, $2.00. 
 
 Price, $2.50. 
 
 Price, $3-50. 
 Price, $4.00. 
 
 Price, $i.so. 
 
 Price, $3.00. 
 
 Price, $r.SO. 
 
 Price, $i.2S. 
 Price, $1.50. 
 
 Price, $1.25. 
 Price, $2.50. 
 Price, $1.25. 
 
 Price. $3-50. 
 
 Price, $3.50. 
 
 Price, $3-00. 
 
 Price, $3-00.
 
 The Political Works of James I 
 
 HARVARD POLITICAL CLASSICS I 
 
 WITH AN INTRODUCTION 
 BY 
 
 CHARLES HOWARD McILWAIN 
 Professor of History and Government in Harvard University 
 
 cxi + 354 pages. $4.00. 
 
 In presenting students of political science with a new edition 
 of the Political Works of James I, Professor Mcllwain has pro- 
 ceeded upon the assumption that a bare outline of mere anatomy 
 of the political thought of a distant age is not sufficient for a scholar. 
 The thorough student needs above all to gain somehow, an appre- 
 ciation of the whole political mind of a period. He must become 
 accustomed to the " intellectual climate " in order to gain a real and 
 sympathetic appreciation of past thought. There is, after all, no 
 road to this goal except the old-fashioned study of contemporary 
 writers in extenso. 
 
 The present volume opens with the " Basilikon Doron," in which 
 King James laid down, for the benefit of his son Prince Henry, 
 his most careful thought in regard to a king's duty towards God, in 
 his office, and in private life. This is followed by " The Trew Law 
 of Free Monarchies," "An Apologie for the Oath of Allegiance," 
 "A Premonition to all Christian Monarches, Free Princes and 
 States," " A Defence of the Right of Kings, against Cardinall du 
 Perron," " Speech of 1603-1604." " Speech of 1605," " Speech of 
 1607," " Speech of 1609-1610," " Speech in the Star Chamber, 
 1616." For the general purpose intended, it was deemed inadvis- 
 able and unnecessary to cumber this text with variant readings or 
 even with explanatory notes. 
 
 To orient the student, however, in his study of the period, the 
 editor has provided an introduction of about one hundred pages, in 
 which he first discusses the rise and growth of the "Anglican 
 Schism " and the development of political ideas accompanying it. 
 This study clears the ground for a consideration in chapter two of 
 the political philosophy of James I, which was summed up in the 
 doctrine of the Divine Right of Kings. Four Appendices discuss 
 the Tudor literature on Church and State, Cowell's " Interpreter," 
 James and the Puritans, and the writings of Robert Parsons. A 
 complete bibliography directs the student to important contemporary 
 and modern works connected with the general field. A compre- 
 hensive index makes both Introduction and text readily accessible. 
 
 HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS 
 44 Randall Hall 280 Madison Ave. 
 
 Cambridge, Mass. Hi New York City
 
 Early Diplomatic Relations 
 
 BETWEEN 
 
 the United States and Mexico 
 
 By WILLIAM R. MANNING, Ph.D. 
 Adjunct Professor of Latin-American History in the University 
 
 of Texas 
 
 418 pages. Cloth, $2.25 
 
 This volume is based on a series of lectures delivered at the 
 Johns Hopkins University in 1913 on the Albert Shaw Founda- 
 tion. It deals with a period in the diplomatic relations between 
 the United States and Mexico, which has hitherto been largely 
 ignored by historians, whose attention has for the most part 
 been centered on the Texas revolution, the admission of Texas 
 into the Union, and the war between the United States and 
 Mexico. 
 
 Early Diplomatic Relations 
 
 BETWEEN 
 
 the United States and Japan 
 
 1853=1865 
 By PAYSON J. TREAT 
 
 Pfofessor of Far Eastern History in Leland Stanford 
 Junior University 
 
 468 pages. l2mo. Cloth, $2.50 
 
 Questions of foreign policy are of course beginning to attract 
 much more attention from Americans than they have in the 
 past. The present volume gives the historical foundations of 
 our commercial intercourse and diplomatic relations with Japan. 
 It is based on an exhaustive study of the documentary sources, 
 supplemented by a knowledge of Japanese institutions and the 
 Japanese point of view gained by two visits to that country. 
 Dr. Treat writes sympathetically of Japanese affairs, and his 
 volume is the most thorough and scholarly treatment that we 
 have had of the period covered. Sound historical work of this 
 character will do much to promote a better understanding of the 
 present-day relations between the two countries. 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 BALTIMORE, MARYLAND
 
 Four Phases of American 
 Development 
 
 FEDERALISM- DEMOCRACY- IMPERIALISM- EXPANSION 
 
 By JOHN BASSETT MOORE, LL.D. 
 
 218 Pases. Crown 8vo. Cloth. Price, $1.50 
 
 The lectures embraced in this volume are designed to sketch in clear and 
 Tiyid outline the great movements by which the historical development of the 
 United States is distinguished and to indicate the causes to which they were 
 due. The order in which the several topics are discussed is not intended to de- 
 note a strict chronological succession ; hence they are described as phases rather 
 than as stages of development. While federalism, democracy and imperialism 
 give a dominant impress to successive periods, yet expansion has characterized 
 the entire course of American history. The misapprehension so widely enter- 
 tained, that imperialism began with the war with Spain is corrected. The im- 
 perialistic tendency, observable from the beginning, is shown to have assumed 
 a specially pronounced form in the Civil War and in the measures of national 
 ■eli-preservation to which that great conflict gave rise. 
 
 The Diplomacy of theWar of 1812 
 
 By FRANK A. UPDYKE, Ph.D. 
 
 504 Pages. Cloth, $2.50 
 
 The aatbor carefully analyzes the diplomatic correspondence in regard to 
 neutral rights and the impressment of seamen which preceded the War of 1812. 
 The protests against interference with neutral trade made by Presidents Jef- 
 ferson and Madison have an unexpectedly familiar sound today. Then, as 
 now the United States was the principal neutral power in a war which in- 
 volved all Europe. The causes of the War of 1812 are clearly set forth. The 
 treaty of Ghent, the hundredth anniversary of which has recently been cele- 
 brated, is the central theme of the latter half of the volume. The negotiations 
 leading to the signing of that treaty are clearly described. The terms of the 
 treaty are examined as well as the questions in dispute which were omitted, 
 and which continued to disturb the relations of the two countries for many 
 years. In the concluding chapter each of these disputed questions is traced to 
 its final solution. 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 BALTIMORE, MARYLAND
 
 A REPRINT OF 
 
 ECONOMIC TRACTS 
 
 The Johns Hopkins Press invites subscriptions to a reprint of four important 
 economic essays of the seventeenth century, to be issued consecutively under the 
 editorial direction of Professor Hollander: — 
 
 A Treatise of the Canker of Englands Common Wealth. By Gerrard db 
 
 Malynks. London, 1601. 
 
 A Discourse of Trade, from England unto the East Indies: Answering to 
 diverse Objections which are usually made against the same. By Thomas 
 MuN. London, 1621. 
 
 The Treasure of Traffike. Or a Discourse of Forraigne Trade. By Lbwes 
 Roberts. London, 1641. 
 
 Brief Observations concerning Trade, and Interest of Money. By JosiAH 
 Child. London, 1668. 
 
 Of the tracts heretofore reprinted, a limited number can yet be obtained as 
 follows. As the editions approach exhaustion, the prices indicated are likely to 
 be increased without notice: — 
 
 Asgill, "Several Assertions Proved" (London, 1696), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 Barbon, "A Discourse of Trade" (London, 1690), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 Berkeley, "The Querist": Parts I, H, III (Dublin, 1735-37), Price, |l.oo. 
 
 Fauquier, "An Essay on Ways and Means" (London, 1756), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 Fortrey, "Englands Interest Considered" (Cambridge, 1663), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 Longe, "A Refutation of the Wage-Fund Theory" (London, 1866), Price, |i.oo. 
 
 Malthus, "An Inquiry into the Nature and Progress of Rent" (London, 1815) 
 (Out of print). 
 
 Massie, "The Natural Rate of Interest" (London, 1750), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 North, " Discourses upon Trade" (London, 1691), Price, 50 cents. 
 
 Ricardo, "Three Letters on 'The Price of Gold' " (London, 1809) (Out of print)! 
 
 Vanderlint, " Money Answers All Things " (London, 1734), Price, $1.00. 
 
 West, "Essay on the Application of Capital to Land" (London, 1815), Price, 
 $1.00. 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 BALTIMORE, MD.
 
 ALBERT SHAW LECTURES ON DIP- 
 LOMATIC HISTORY 
 
 1899. John H. Latan6. The Diplomatic Relations of 
 the United States and Spanish America. 1900. 
 (Out of print.) 
 
 1900. James Morton Callahan. The Diplomatic 
 History of the Southern Confederacy. 1901. 
 (Out of print.) 
 
 1906. Jesse Siddall Reeves. American Diplomacy 
 under Tyler and Polk. 1907. $1.50. 
 
 1907. Elbert Jay Benton. International Law and 
 Diplomacy of the Spanish- American War. 1908. 
 $1.50. 
 
 1909. Ephraim Douglas Adams. British Interests 
 and Activities in Texas, 1838-1846. 1910. $1.50. 
 
 1911. Charles Oscar Paullin. Diplomatic Nego- 
 tiations of American Naval Officers, 1778-1883. 
 1912. $2.00. 
 
 1912. Isaac J. Cox. The West Florida Controversy, 
 1798-1813. 1918. $3.00. 
 
 1913. William R. Manning. Early Diplomatic Re- 
 lations between the United States and Mexico. 
 
 1916. $2.25. 
 
 1914. Frank A. Updike. The Diplomacy of the War 
 of 1812. 1915. $2.50. 
 
 1917. Payson J. Treat. Early Diplomatic Relations 
 between the United States and Japan, 1853-1865. 
 
 1917. $2.50. 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 BALTIMORE, MARYLAND
 
 JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY STUDIES 
 
 IN 
 
 Historical and Political Science 
 
 Edited b^ HERBERT B. ADAMS, 1882-1901 
 
 * Not sold separately. 
 
 FIRST SERIES.— 1883.— $4.00. 
 
 (Volume sold only with complete s€t.) 
 Z. An Introdnctlon to American Institutional History. By E. A. Fbbbuan. 25 centa. 
 n. The Germanic Origin of New England Towns. By H. B. Adams. 50 cents, 
 m. Local Government in Illinois. By Albebt Shaw. — Local GoTernment In Fennel- 
 
 vania. By B. R. L. Gould. 30 cents. 
 rv. Saxon TIthingmen in America. By H. B. Adams. 50 cents. 
 ▼. Local Government In Uichlgan and the Northwest. By E. W. Bbmis. 26 centa. 
 VI. Parish Institntions of Maryland. By Edward Imqlb. 40 cents. 
 •VH. Old Maryland Manors. By John Hbmsley Johnson. 
 VIII, Norman Constables in America. By H. B. Adams. 50 cents. 
 IZ-X. Village Communities of Cape Ann and Salem, By H. B. Adams. 60 cents. 
 
 XI, The Genesis of a New England State. By A. Johnston. 30 cents. 
 *ZII, Local Government and Schools In South Carolina, By B. J. Ramaob. 
 
 SECOND SERIES.— 1884. 
 (Volume sold only with complete sets.) 
 •I-n, Methods of Historical Study. By H. B. Adams. 
 m. The Past and Present of Political Economy. By R. T. Ely, 85 centa. 
 rv. Samuel Adams, the Man of the Town Meeting. By Jambs K. Hosmbb. S5 cents. 
 V-VI. Taxation in the TInlted States. By Hbney Cabtbe Adams. 50 cents. 
 Vn. Institutional Beginnings in a Western State. By Jbsbb Mact. 25 cents. 
 Vm-IX, Indian Money In New England, etc. By William B. Wbbdbn. 60 -cents. 
 •X. Town and County Government In the Colonies. By B. Channinq. 
 •XI. Rudimentary Society among Boys. By J. Hkmslex Johnson. 
 
 XII. Land Laws of Mining Districts. By C. H. Shinn. 60 cents. 
 
 THIRD SERIES.— 1885.— 94,00. 
 
 Z. Maryland's Influence upon Land Cessions to the IT, 8, By H. B. Adams. T6 csnts. 
 n-III. Virginia Local Institutions. By E. Inglb. 75 cents. 
 
 IV. Recent American Socialism. By Richabd T. Ely. 50 cents. 
 V-VI-VII. Maryland Local Institutions, By Lbwis W. Wu.hblm. $1.00. 
 
 Vni, Influence of the Proprietors In Founding New Jersey. By A. Scott. 26 cents. 
 ZX-X. American Constitutions, By Hobacb Datis. 50 cents. _ 
 
 ZI-XII, Ths City of Washington. By J. A. Pobtbb. 50 centa. M 
 
 FOURTH SERIES.— 1886.— $4.00. 
 
 •1, Dutch Village Communities on the Hudson River. By I. Bltino. 
 
 ZI-III, Town Government In Rhode Island. By W. E. Fostbb. — The NarrsgaBiStt Flaat- 
 
 ers. By Edward Channinq. 50 cents. 
 rv. Pennsylvania Boroughs. By William P. Holcomb. 50 cents. 
 
 V. Introduction to Constitutional History of the States. By J. F. Jambson. 50 CSBtS. 
 
 VI. The Puritan Colony at Annapolis, Maryland, By D. R. Randall. 50 cents. 
 VII-VIII-IX. The Land duestion in the United States. By S. Sato. $1.00. 
 
 X. Town and City Government of New Haven. By C. H. Lbtbbmobb. 60 cents. 
 XI-XII, Land System of the New England Colonies. By M. Eolbston. 60 cents. 
 
 FIFTH SERIES.— 1887.— 93.50. 
 
 I-H. city Government of Philadelphia. By E. P. Allinson and B. Pbnbosb. 60 cents. 
 
 III. City Government of Boston. By James M. Bdgbeb. 25 cents, 
 
 •IV. City Government of St. Louis. By Marshall S. Snow. 
 
 V-VI. Local Government In Canada. By John George Bodbinot. 60 centa. 
 
 VII. Effect of the War of 1812 upon the American Union. By N. M. Butlbb. 26 eentH 
 
 VIII. Notes on the Literature of Charities. By Hbbbebt B. Adams. 25 centa. 
 
 IX. Predictions of Hamilton and De Tocquevllle. By Jambs Bbycb. 25 centa. 
 
 X. The Study of History In England and Scotland. By P. Fbbdbbicq. 26 cents. 
 
 XI. Seminary Libraries and University Extension, By H. B. Adams. 26 cents. 
 •XII. European Schools of History and Politics. By A. D. Whitd. 
 
 SIXTH SERIES.— x888.— 93.50. 
 The History of Cooperation in the United States.
 
 SEVENTH SERIES.— 1889. 
 
 (Volume sold only with complete set.) 
 I. Arnold Toynbee. By F. C. Montaqub. 60 cents. 
 
 n-UI. Municipal Government in San Francisco. By Bbrnaso Moses. 60 centii. 
 IV. Municipal History of New Orleans. By Wm. W. Howb. 25 cents. 
 •V-VI. English Culture in Virginia. By William P. Tkbnt. 
 
 YII-VIII-IX. The Biver Towns of Connecticut. By Charlbs M. Andsbwb. fl.OO. 
 •X-XI-XII. Federal Government in Canada. By John G. Booeinot. 
 
 EIGHTH SERIES.— 1890. 
 
 (Volume sold only with complete set.) 
 
 I-II. The Begrlnnin^s of American Nationality. By A. W. Small. fl.OO. 
 
 ni. Local Government in Wisconsin. By D. B. Spencer. 25 cents. 
 
 •IV. Spanish Colonization in the Southwest. By P. W. Blackmab. 
 
 V-VI. The Study of History in Germany and France. By P. Fehdhricq. |1.00. 
 
 VII-IX. Progress of the Colored People of Maryland. By J. R. Bbace:iitt. f 1.00. 
 
 •X. The Study of History in Belgium and Holland. By P. Feedbeicq. 
 
 XI-XII. Seminary Notes on Historical Literature. By H. B. Adams and othen. 60 c«nta. 
 
 NINTH SERIES.— 1891. 
 
 •l-II. Government of the TTnited States. By W. W. Willodghbt and W. P. Willodohbt. 
 Ill-rV. TTniversity Education in Maryland. By B. C. Steineb. The Johns Hopkiaa 
 
 University (1876-1891). By D. C. Gilman. 50 cents. 
 •V-VI. Municipal ITnity in the Lombard Communes. By W. K. Williams. 
 VII-VIII, Public Lands of the Eoman Republic. By A. Stephenson. 75 cents. 
 IX, Constitutional Development of Japan. By T. Itbnaoa. 50 cents. 
 •X. A History of Liberia. By J. H. T. McPherson. 
 XI-XII, The Indian Trade in Wisconsin. By P. J. Tobnbb. 50 cents. 
 
 TENTH SERIES.— 1892.— ^3.50. 
 
 I. The Bishop Hill Colony, By Michael A. Mikkblsbn. 50 cents. 
 
 n-III. Church and State In New England, By Paul B. Laueb. 50 cents. 
 
 rv. Church and State in Maryland. By Georgm Pbtrie. 50 cents. 
 
 V-VI, Eeliglous Development of North Carolina. By S. B. Weeks. 50 cents. 
 
 VII. Maryland's Attitude in the Struggle for Canada, By J. W. Black. 50 cents. 
 
 VIII-IX, The Quakers in Pennsylvania. By A. C. Applegabth. 75 cents. 
 
 X-XI, Columbus and his Discovery of America. By H. B. Adams and H. WOOB. 60 cents. 
 
 XII. Causes of the American Bevolutlon. By J. A. Woodbubn. 50 cents. 
 
 ELEVENTH SERIES.— 1893.— $3.50. 
 
 I, The Social Condition of Labor, By E. R. L. Godld. 50 cents. 
 
 II, The World's Representative Assemblies of To-Day, By E. K. Aldbn. 50 cents, 
 ni-rv. The Negro in the District of Columbia, By Edward Ingle. $1.00. 
 
 V-VI, Church and State in North Carolina. By Stephen B. Weeks. 50 cents. 
 VII-VIII. The Condition of the Western Farmer, etc. By A. P. Bbntlbt. $1.00. 
 rX-X. History of Slavery in Connecticut, By Bernard C. Steineb. 75 cents. 
 Xl-Xn. Local Government in the South. By E. W. Bemis and others. $1.00. 
 
 TWELFTH SERIES.— 1894.— ^3.50. 
 
 I-II. The Cincinnati Southern Railway. By J. H. Holi.ander. $1.00. 
 
 QI. Constitutional Beginnings of North Carolina. By J. S. Bassbtt. 60 cents. 
 
 tV. Struggle of Dissenters for Toleration in Virginia, By H. R. McIlwainb. 50 cent«. 
 
 ^-VI-VII. The Carolina Pirates and Colonial Commerce, By S. C. Hdqhson. $1.00. 
 
 9HI-IX. Representation and Suffrage in Massachusetts, By G. H. Hatnes. 50 cents. 
 
 X.. English Institutlon-3 and the American Indian, By J. A. James. 25 cents. 
 
 SI-XII, International Beginnings of the Congo Free State, By J. S. Rbevbb. 50 cents. 
 
 THIRTEENTH SERIES.— 1895.— $350. 
 t-n. Government of the Colony of South Carolina. By E. L. Whitney. 75 cents. 
 [U-rV. Early Relations of Maryland and Virginia, By J, H. LatanAi. 50 cents. 
 V, The Rise of the Bicameral System in America, By T. P. Moban. 50 cents. 
 n-Yll. White Servitude in the Colony of Virginia, By J. C. Ballagh. 50 cents. 
 Till. The Genesis of California's First Constitution, By R. D. Hunt. 50 cents. 
 CX, Benjamin Franklin as an Economist. By W. A. Wbtzbi- 60 cents. 
 C. The Provisional Government of Maryland, By J. A. Silver. 56 cents. 
 U-XII, Government and Religion of the Virginia Indians, By S. R. Hbndbbn. 60 eenta 
 
 FOURTEENTH SERIES.— 1896.— «3-5o. 
 
 [. Constitutional History of Hawaii, By Hen by B. Chambers. 25 cents. 
 
 3. City Government of Baltimore. By Thaddeus P. Thomas. 25 cents. 
 
 CH, Colonial Origins of New England Senates, By P. L. Riijiy. 50 cents. 
 
 rV-V. Servitude in the Colony of North Carolina, By J. S. Bassbtt. 50 cents. 
 
 n-VII, Representation In Virginia. By J. A. C. Chandlbb. 50 cents. 
 
 mi. History of Taxation in Connecticut (1636-1776). By P. R. Jonbs. 60 cents. 
 
 TC-X, A Study of Slavery in New Jersey. By Hbnby S. Coolby. 50 cents. 
 
 U-XII. Causes of the Maryland Revolution of 1689, By P. E. Spabks. 50 cents.
 
 FIFTEENTH SERIES.— 1897.— $3-50. 
 I-II. The Tobacco Industry In Virginia since 1860. By B. W. Abnold. 50 cents. 
 m-V. Street Hallway System of Philadelphia. By F, W. Spbibs. 75 c«it«. 
 VI. Daniel Haymond. By C. P. Nbill. 50 cents. ,« ^ 
 
 VII-VIII. Economic History of B. & O. H. R. By M. Rbizbnstbin. 50 cents. 
 IX The South American Trade of Baltimore. By F. R. Rdttbh, 50 cents. 
 X-ZI State Tax Commissions in the United States. By J. W. Chapman. 50 cent*. 
 XII Tendencies In American Economic Thought. By S. Shbbwood. 25 cents. 
 
 SIXTEENTH SERIES.— 1898.— $3.50. 
 
 I-IV. The Neutrality of the American Lakes, etc. By J. M. Callahan. $1.25. Cloth, % 
 V. West Florida. By H. E. Chambbks. 25 cents. 
 
 VT. Anti-Slavery Leaders of North Carolina. By J. S. Bassett. 50 cents. 
 vil-IX. Life and Administration of Sir Bobert Eden. By B. C. Stbinhe. $1.00. 
 X-XI. The Transition of North Carolina from a Colony. By E. W. Sikbs. 50 
 XII. Jared Sparks and Alexis De TocqueTlIle. By H. B. Adaus. 25 cents. 
 
 cent 
 
 SEVENTEENTH SERIES.— 1899.— ^3.50. 
 
 $1.00. 
 75 cents. 
 
 I-n-III. History of State Banking in Maryland. By A. C. Bbtan. 
 rV-V. The Know-Nothing Party In Maryland. By L. F. Schmbckbbieb. 
 VI. The Labadlst Colony in Maryland. By B. B. Jambs. 50 cents. 
 yiI_Vlll. History of Slavery in North Carolina. By J. S. Bassbtt. 75 cents. 
 IX-X-XI. Development of the Chesaneake & Ohio Canal. By Q. W. Wabd. 75 centak 
 XII. Public Educational "Work in Baltimore. By Hbbbbbt B. Adams. 25 cents. 
 
 EIGHTEENTH SERIES.— 1900.— ^3.50. 
 
 I-rv. studies In State Taxation. Edited by J. H. Hollandbb. Paper, $1.00 ; cloth, $1.3 
 V-VI. The Colonial Executive Prior to the Restoration. By P. L. Kaxb. 50 cents. 
 Vn. Constitution and Admission of Iowa into the TJnion. By J. A. Jambs. 30 cents. 
 VIII-IX. The Church and Popular Education. By H. B. Adams. 50 cents. 
 X-XII. Religious Freedom in Virginia: The Baptists. By W. T. Thom. 75 cents. 
 
 NINETEENTH SERIES.— 1901.— 33.50. 
 
 X-in. America In the Pacific and the Far East. By J. M. Callahan. 75 cents. 
 
 rV-V. State Activities In Relation to Labor. By W. F. Willodohbt. 50 cents. 
 
 Vl-Vn. History of Suffrage in Virginia. By J. A. C. Chandlbb. 50 cents. 
 
 Vm-IX. The Maryland Constitution of 1864. By W. S. Mtbbs. 50 cents. 
 
 X. Life of Commissary James Blair. By D. E. Motley. 25 cents. 
 
 XI-XU. Got. Hicks of Maryland and the Civil War. By Q. L. BAi»CLi7ra. 60 cents. 
 
 TWENTIETH SERIES.— 190a.— 13.50. 
 
 I. Western Maryland In the Revolution. By B. C. Stbinbb. 30 cents. 
 
 II-III. State Banks since the National Bank Act. By G. E. Babnbtt. 50 cents. 
 
 IV. Early History of Internal Improvements In Alabama. By W. E. Mabtin. 80 cent 
 •V-VI. Trust Companies in the United States. By Gkobgb Catob. 
 VII-VIII. The Maryland Constitution of 1851. By J. W. Habby. 50 cents. 
 IX-X. Political Activities of Philip Freheau. By S. E. Fobman. 50 cents. 
 XI.-XII. Continental Opinion on a Middle European Tariff Union. By G. M. Fiss. 80 1 
 
 TWENTY-FIRST SERIES.— 1903.— 13.50. 
 
 •I-II. The Wabash Trade Route. By E. J. Benton. 
 
 Hl-rv. Internal Improvements in North Carolina. By C. C. Wbavbb. 50 cents. 
 
 V. History of Japanese Paper Currency. By M. Takaki. 30 cents. 
 VI-VII. Economics and Politics In Maryland, 1720-1760, and the Fnbllo Serrioes 
 
 Daniel Dulany the Elder. By St. Q. L. Siodssat. 50 cents. 
 •Vni-lX-X. Beginnings of Maryland, 1631-1639. By B. C. Stbinbb. 
 XI-XII. The English Statutes In Maryland. By St. G. L. Siodssat. 50 cents, 
 
 TWENTY-SECOND SERIES.— 1904.— $3.50. 
 
 I-n. A Trial Bibliography of American Trade-Union Publications. 50 cents. 
 
 Ill-rv. White Servitude in Maryland, 1634-1820. By E. I. McCobmac. 50 cents. 
 
 V. Switzerland at the Beginning of the Sixteenth Century. By J. M. Vincent. 80 cen' 
 
 VI-VII-VIII. The History of Reconstruction in Virginia. By H. J. Eckbnbodb. 50 cents. 
 
 IX-X. The Foreign Commerce of Japan since the Restoration. By Y. Hattobl 60 cents. 
 
 3U-3CII. Descriptions of Maryland. By B. C. Steinek. 50 cents. 
 
 TWENTY-THIRD SERIES.— 1905.— $3.50. 
 
 t 
 
 Jl?U?®'^°°^*'^^*'**°'' ^" South Carolina. By J. P. Holi.is. 50 cents. 
 
 n*;^' St**e Government in Maryland, 1777-1781. By B. W. Bond, Jb. 50 cents. 
 
 Xry^* Colonial Administration under Lord Clarendon, 1660-1667. By P. L,. Kayb. 50 cti, 
 
 VTI-yill. Justice In Colonial Virginia. By O. P. Chitwood. 50 cents. 
 
 ^"^;»^^® Napoleonic Exiles In America, 1816-1819. By J. S. Reeves. 50 cents. 
 
 XI-XII. Municipal Problems In Mediaeval Switzerland. By J. M. Vincbnt. 50 cents. 
 
 .^1
 
 TWENTY-FOURTH SERIES.— 1906.— $3-5o. 
 
 I-n. Bpanlah-Amerlcan Diplomatic Helatlons before 1898. By H. B. Flack. 50 cents. 
 m-IV. The Finances of American Trade Unions. By A. M. Sakolski. 75 cents. 
 V-VI. Diplomatic Negotiations of the United States with Bussla. By J. C. Hildt. 60 cU. 
 Vn-VIII. State Rights and Parties In North Carolina, 1776-1831. By H. M. Waqstaff. 60c. 
 ZZ-X. National Labor Federations In the United States. By William Eibk. 75 cent*. 
 ZI-XII. Maryland During the English Civil "Wars. Part I. By B. C. Stbinbb. 50 centl. 
 
 TWENTY-FIFTH SERIES.— 1907.— 13.50. 
 
 I. Internal Taxation in the Philippines. By John S. Hobd. 30 cents. 
 IX-III. The Monroe Mission to France, 1794-1796. By B. W. Bond, Jr. 60 cents. 
 rV-V. Maryland During the English Civil "Wars, Part II. By Bbbnaed C. Stbineb. BOc. 
 VI-VH. The State in Constitutional and International Law. By E. T. Cbanh. 50 cents. 
 VIII-IX-X. Financial History of Maryland, 1789-1848. By Hdgh S. Hanna. 75 cents. 
 XI-XII. Apprenticeship in American Trade Unions. By J. M. Motlbt. 50 cents. 
 
 TWENTY-SIXTH SERIES.— 1908.— $3.50. 
 
 I-III. British Committees, Commissions, and Councils of Trade and Plantations, 1621^ 
 
 1676. By C. M. Andrews. 75 cents. 
 rV-VI. Neutral Eights and Obligations in the Anglo-Boer War. By R. G. Campbblu 
 
 75 cents. 
 yil-VIII. The Elizabethan Parish in its Ecclesiastical and Financial Aspects. By S. L. 
 
 Ware. 50 cents. 
 IX-X. A Study of the Topography and Municipal History of Praeneste. By R. V. D. 
 
 Magoffin. 50 cents. 
 XI-XII. Beneficiary Features of American Trade Unions, By J. B. Kennedy. 50 cents. 
 
 TWENTY-SEVENTH SERIES.— 1909.— $3.50. 
 
 I-II. The Self-Heconstruction of Maryland, 1864-1867. By W. S. Mybbs. 60 cents. 
 III-IV-V. The Development of the English Law of Conspiracy. By J. W. Bbtak. 
 
 75 cents. 
 
 YI-YII, Legislative and Judicial History of the Fifteenth Amendment. By J. M. 
 
 Mathews. 75 cents ; cloth $1. 
 7III-XII. England and the French Bevolutlon, 1789-1797. By W. T. Lafbadb. $1. 
 
 TWENTY-EIGHTH SERIES.— 1910.— $3.50. 
 (Complete In four numbers.) 
 
 I. History of Beconstrnetion in Louisiana (Through 1868). By J. R. Ficelbn. fl.OOt 
 
 cloth $1.25. 
 n. The Trade Union Label. By E. R. Speddbn. 50 cents ; cloth 75 cents. 
 ni. The Doctrine of Non-Suability of the State in the United States. By E. Sinqb- 
 
 wald. 50 cents ; cloth 75 cents. 
 ly, David Bicardo: A Centenary Estimate. By J. H. Hollandeb. fl.OO; cloth |1.26. 
 
 TWENTY-NINTH SERIES.— 191 1.— $3.50. 
 (Complete In three nnmbers.) 
 
 I. Maryland Under the Commonwealth: A Chronicle of the years 1649-1658. By B. C. 
 
 Stbinbe. $1 ; cloth $1.25. 
 
 II. The Dutch Bepublio and the American Bevolution. By Fsibdbich Edlbb. |1.50: 
 
 cloth $1.75. 
 in. The Closed Shop in American Trade Unions. By F. T. Stockton. $1.00 ; cloth $1.25. 
 
 THIRTIETH SERIES.— 1912.— $3.50. 
 
 (Complete in three numbers.) 
 
 I. Beoent Administration in Virginia. By F. A. Mageddeb. $1.26; cloth 11.50. 
 
 IZ. The Standard Bate in America Trade Unions. By D. A. McCabb. $1.26; doth 
 
 $1.50. 
 HZ. Admission to American Trade Unions. By F. E. Wolfb. $1.00 ; cloth $1.26. 
 
 THIRTY-FIRST SERIES.— 1913— ^350. 
 
 (Complete In four numbers.) 
 
 L The Land System In Maryland, 1780-1766, By Clabbncb P. Qodld. 75 cents; clot* 
 
 $1.00. 
 Zl. The Government of American Trade Unions. By T. W. Olockbb. $1.00 ; cloth $1.28. 
 ZIZ. The Free Negro in Virginia, 1619-1866. By J. H. Rd83BLL. $1.00; cloth $1.26. 
 rv. The Quiniiuennalei : An Historical Study. By B. V. D. Maqoitin. 60 cents; cloth 
 
 76 cents. 
 
 xi
 
 THIRTY-SECOND SERIES.— 1914— 1350. 
 
 (Complete in three numbera.) 
 L jBrlidlotloB In American Bulldln^-Tradet Unions. By N. B. WHinmr. 11.00; 
 
 n. SUTery in klBtourl, 1804-1886. By H. A. Thbxlbb. 11.25; cloth 11.80. 
 fTT, OolonUl Trade of MaryUnd. By M. S, Mobbiss. 11.00 ; cloth 11.25. 
 
 THIRTY-THIRD SERIES.— 1915.— •3-50. 
 (Complete In four numbers.) 
 L Money and Traniportatlon In Maryland, 1720-176K. By ClABBMCB P. GouU). 7S 
 
 XZ. T^ rUianolal AdminlBtratlon of the Colony of YlrflnU. By Pbect Scott Flcppix. 
 
 60 cento; cloth 75 cents. _ , „ . »> ^ ,, . .».-*_. 
 
 nZ. The Helper and American Trade TJnloni. By Johm H. Ashwobth. 75 c«Bti; 
 
 XT. The Conetitntlonal Dootrlnei of Justice Harlan. By Flotd Babzilia Ci^ass. fl.OO ; 
 
 cloth 11.26. 
 
 THIRTY-FOURTH SERIES.— i9i6.--$3.5o. 
 
 (Complete In four numbers.) 
 
 I. The Boycott In American Trade Unions. By Leo Wolman. $1.00; cloth, $1.25. 
 
 II. The Postal Power of Congress. By Lindsat Rogeks. $1.00 ; cloth, $1.25. 
 
 m. The Control of Strikes in American Trade Unions. By G. M. Janes. 75 cents; 
 
 cloth, fl.OO. ^ ^, 
 
 ly. state Administration In Maryland. By John L. DoNAU>soir. $1.00; cloth $1.25. 
 
 THIRTY-FIFTH SERIES.— 1917.— $4.00. 
 
 (Complete In three numbers.) 
 
 X. The Virginia Committee System and the American Revolution. By J. M. Lbaxjd. 
 
 $1.00; cloth $1.25. 
 IT. The Organizability of Labor. By W. O. Wbtfokth. $1.50; cloth $1.75. 
 Zn. Party Organization and Machinery In Michigan since 1890. By A. C. MiUiSPAlTOH. 
 $1.00 ; cloth $1.25. 
 
 THIRTY-SIXTH SERIES.— 1918.— $4.00. 
 
 (Complete in four numbers.) 
 
 I. The Standard of Living in Japan. By K. Morimoto. $1.25; cloth $1.50. 
 
 II. Sumptuary Law in NHmDerg. By K. R. Greenfield. $1.25; cloth $1.50. 
 
 III. The Privileges and Immunities of State Citizenship. By R. Howblu $100; 
 cloth $1.25. 
 
 rv. French Protestantism, 1669-1562. By C. G. Keixt. .$1.25; cloth $1.50. 
 
 The set of thirty-six series is offered, uniformly bound in cloth, for library use for $126.00 
 net. The separate volumes may also be had bound in cloth at the prices stated. 
 
 NOTES SUPPLEMENTARY TO THE STUDIES IN HISTORY 
 AND POLITICS. 
 
 PBICC OF THESB NOTBB, TBN CENTS NUT BACH, UMLBSS OTHBBWISB BTATBD. j 
 
 Mnnlcipal Government In England. By Albbbt Shaw. 
 
 loeial 'W^ork in Australia and London. By Williau Gbbt. 
 
 Encouragement of Higher Education. By H. B. Adaus. , 
 
 The Problem of City Government. By Sbth Low. 
 
 Work Among the Workingwomen of Baltimore. By H. B. Adams. 
 
 Charities: The Belation of the State, the City, and the Individual to Modem mit^ 
 
 thropio Work. By A. G. Wabnbb. 
 Law and History. By Walthb B. Scaifh. 
 
 The Needs of Self-Supporting Women. By Clabb db Gbaffbnbbid. i 
 
 Early Preshyterlanism in Maryland. By J. W. McIlvain. i 
 
 The Educational Aspect of the U. 8. Katlonal Mnseom. By O. T. Mason. 
 University Extension and the University of the Future. By Biceabd G. Mouiaoh. 
 The Philosophy of Education. By William T. Habbis. 
 Popular Election of U. 8. Senators. By John Hatnhs. 
 A Memorial of Lucius S. Merrlam. By J. H. Hollandbb and others. 
 Za History Past Politics 1 By Hbbbbet B. Adams. 
 
 Lay Sermons. By Amos G. Wabnbb ; with a biographical sketch by Gboboi B. HowiJBi. 
 Price twenty-flve cents.
 
 Extra Volumes of Studies 
 
 IN 
 
 Historical and Political Science 
 
 Those marked with an asterisk (♦) are out of print. 
 *I. The Bepublic of New Haven, By Charles H, Lbvbbmoee. 342 pages. 
 II. Philadelphia, 1681-1887. By Edwaed P. Allison, A.M., and Boies Pen- 
 rose, A.B. 444 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $3.00. 
 *III. Baltimore and the Nineteenth of April, 1861. By Geobqb Wiixiam 
 
 Brown. 176 pages. 
 lY. Local Constitutional History of the United States, By George E. Howard, 
 Ph.D. — Volume I — Development of the Township, Hundred and Shire. 
 542 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $3.00. 
 VI, The Negro in Maryland. By Jeffrey B. Brackett, Ph.D. 270 pages. 
 
 8vo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 VII. The Supreme Court of the United States, By W. W. Willooghby, Ph.D. 
 
 124 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $1.25. 
 VIII, The Intercourse between the IT. S. and Japan. By Inazo (Ota) Nitobb, 
 
 Ph.D. 198 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $1.25. 
 *IX. State and Federal Government in Switzerland, By John Martin Yimcbnt. 
 250 pages. 
 X. Spanish Institutions of the Southwest. By Frank W. Blackmab, Ph.D. 
 380 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 XI. An Introduction to the Study of the Constitution. By Morris M. Cohn. 
 
 250 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $1.50. 
 XII, The Old English Manor. By C. M. Andrews, Ph.D. 280 pages. 8vo. 
 Cloth, $1.50. 
 ♦XIII. America: Its Geographical History, 1492-1892. By Walter B. Scaifb, 
 
 176 pages. 
 •XIV. Florentine Life During the Eenaissance. By Walter B. Scaifb. 
 XV. The Southern Quakers and Slavery. By Stephen B. Weeks, Ph.D. 414 
 
 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 XVI. Contemporary American Opinion of the French Bevolution. By C. D. 
 
 Hazbn, Ph.D. 325 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 XVII, Industrial Experiments in the British Colonies of North America. By 
 Eleanor L. Lord. 164 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $1.25. 
 XVIII. State Aid to Higher Education: A Series of Addresses at the Johns Hop- 
 kins University. 100 pages. 8vo. Cloth. $1.00. 
 XIX. Irrigation in Utah. By C. H. Brough. 228 pages. 
 XX. Financial History 'of Baltimore. By J. H. Hollander, Ph.D. 400 pages. 
 
 8vo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 XXI. Cuba and International Helations. By J. M. Callahan. 503 pages. Svo. 
 
 Cloth. $3.00. 
 XXII. The American "Workman. By E. Levasseur (translation). 540 pages. 
 Svo. Cloth. $3.00. 
 
 XXIII. Herbert B. Adams. A Memorial Volume. 232 pages. Svo. Cloth. 
 
 XXIV. A History of Slavery in Virginia. By J. C. Ballagh. 160 pages. Svo. 
 
 Cloth. $1.50. 
 XXV. The Finances and Administration of Providence, 1636-1901. By Howard 
 
 K. Stokes. 474 pages. Svo. Cloth. $3.50. 
 XXVI. The Adoption of the Fourteenth Amendment. By Horace B. Flack. 
 286 pages. Svo. Cloth. $2.00. 
 
 NEW SERIES. 
 
 I. The Eevision and Amendment of State Constitutions. W. P. DODD. 
 368 pages. Svo. Cloth. $2.00.
 
 The West Florida Controversy 
 of 1798-1813 
 
 A Study in American Diplomacy 
 
 By ISAAC JOSLIN COX 
 
 Aatooiate Profeaser of HUtory. Unirarsity of Cincianati 
 
 710 Pages. 12mo. $3.00. 
 
 This volume has recently been published in the series of the Albert i 
 Shaw Lectures on Diplomatic History. It is based on lectures de- 
 livered in the Johns Hopkins University in 1912, and later revised 
 for publication. The subject involves one of the most intricate prob- 
 lems in American history, and Professor Cox has spared no pains 
 in searching for new sources of information. He has not only 
 availed himself of the collections in Washington and of the 
 material in the Department of Archives and History at Jackson, 
 Mississippi, but he has personally searched the Archives at Seville 
 and Madrid. 
 
 The volume deals with the secret intrigues of statesmen and J 
 diplomats in the capitals of America and Europe on the one hand, 
 and with the aggressive, irresponsible movements of impatient 
 frontiersmen on the other. Professor Cox thinks that the sturdy 
 pioneers of the Southwest outstripped the diplomats, and that 
 their deeds were the decisive factors in the settlement of the long 
 and bitter controversy that was waged over West Florida. 
 
 THE JOHNS HOPKINS PRESS 
 
 BALTIMORE, MARYLAND
 
 UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 
 
 AA 000 964 631 6