College of Agriculture Agricultural Experiment Station Berkeley, California ECONOMIC AND LEGAL ASPECTS OF COMPULSORY PRORATION IN AGRICULTURAL MARKETING E. A. Stokdyk March, 1933 w* UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA I % ; LIBRARY ' BRANCH OF THE Contribution from the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics (Preliminary report) LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA DAVIS /' i I 1 t 1 4 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Introduction 1 Purpose of study . 1 Proposals for effecting proration 3 Probable legal status of proration in agricultural marketing 5 The rule of reason 5 Legal status of cooperatives and trade restraint . » , , 6 Proration in oil reviewed by courts ..... 8 Legistic theories justifying proration .... 10 Proration and interstate commerce .... 12 Proration and price fixing ..... 12 Attempts to increase returns through voluntary prorate programs .... 12 Proration of lemon shipments ......... 14 Valencia orange proration .... 15 Tokay grape prorate . 16 Lettuce proration 16 Cantaloupe proration 17 Watsonville apple prorate .... ... 17 Canning peach limitation program 17 California Grape Control Board operations 18 Summary of proration attempts . 18 Problems of administration of compulsory prorate programs 19 Determining an industry's desire for proration 19 Determining the extent to prorate ..... 19 Distribution of benefits and burdens 19 Enforcement 21 Financing 21 Appraisal of the desirability and feasibility of prorate programs ... 21 Summary 25 ECONOMIC AND LEGAL ASPECTS OF COMPULSORY PRORATION IN AGRICULTURAL MARKETING E. A, Stokdyk fyty INTRODUCTION Purpose of Study.-- The purpose of this study is to appraise the desir- ability and feasibility of compulsory proration programs as a means of increasing returns to the producers of some California agricultural commodities. The primary question which arises with reference to compulsory proration is its legality, that is, whether or not it is constitutional. It was endeavored to ascertain the probable legal status through an analysis of legislative acts and court decisions that seemed pertinent to the problem. At the same time, the economic possibilities of the plan were considered. This was done through a sur- vey of the attempts of several groups of California producers to prorate the marketing of their crops and by summarizing some of the studies made by the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics on the factors affecting the prices of soecific crops. This study was made at the request of the California State Farm Bureau Federation and the California State Chamber of Commerce. Their request was an expression of the fact that numerous farmers have reached the point where they are willing to recognize and enforce the "right of the lot" . This is not a new philosophy; it was manifested in the practices of the early English merchant and craft guilds. These were associations of persons enjoying a charter by public authority which endowed them with an exclusive right to practice their craft in the community. Through it the "right of the lot" was recognized and enforced. Since there was a narrow outlet available for the wares, each member of a guild was held to a "stint" or a prorated allotment of the common market opportunity of the guild. \/ To sell more than a specified allotment or "stint" was forbidden. There was also a prohibition against employing more than a specified number of journeymen and apprentices. Thus the guildsmen by means of group control made sure of a common disposal of economic opportunity. Americans, surrounded on all sides by an abundance of natural resources and expanding markets, have been slow in adopting the philosophy that the indi- vidual needs to be controlled or restrained by his fellows in the common interest and for his own protection. They have held tenaciously to a philosophy of un- limited competition. It was believed that free access to production and free competition could be relied upon to guarantee remunerative returns to producers. v/ Preliminary report. Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. March 30, 1933. 2/ Associate Professor of Agricultural Economics, Associate Agricultural Econ- omist on the Giannini Foundation, and Associate Agricultural Economist in the Experiment Station. Mr . Spencer Sparks, Technical Assistant, aided in collecting and assembling the data presented. 4/Perlman, Selig. A theory of the labor movement, p. 254-261, Macmillan Company, 1928. 1 t 1 r I I r ? j > 4 2. The philosophy of unlimited competition contributed to the rapid develop- ment of a growing nation. Many who have appraised it believe that it was well adapted to pioneer conditions.^ Now, however, that the United States has attain- ed a complex industrial structure and a specialized agriculture, problems of un- balanced oroduction are becoming more acute, and a number of groups have found, particularly in periods of violent economic disturbances, that the remunerative outlets for production are limited. Under these conditions the practicability of the philosophy of unlimited competition is challenged. There is a call for con- trol of competition with administration by groups as in the period of the guilds in England. The trend toward this philosophy, although not readily distinguish- able until the post-war period, is now unmistakable.^ A few farmers' cooperative marketing agencies, although not primarily organized for such a purpose, have endeavored to limit competition by restricting the volume marketed in the primary channels of trade through a "growers' contract" in which the individual grower agrees to further his own and group interest through taking part in such action. Other groups of farmers have endeavored to accomplish the same objective by forming "control" organizations which include all or most marketing agencies both cooperative and proprietary. See pages 12 to 19 for a summary of some attempts. Pound, Roscoe. The spirit of the common law. Marshall Jones Co. Boston. 1921. s/ Justice Brandeis in New State Ice Co. vs. Liebmann (52 SC + 371 - 1932) sets forth this trend in philosophy clearly in the following words: "The people of the United States are now confronted with an emergency more serious than war. Misery is wide-spread, in a time, not of scarcity but of overabundance. The long-continued depression has brought unprecedented unemployment, a catastrophic fall in commodity prices and a volume of economic losses which threatens our financial institutions. Some people believe that the existing conditions threaten even the stability of our capitalistic system. Economists are search- ing for the cause of this disorder and are reexamining the bases of our indus- trial structure. Business men are seeking possible remedies. Most of them real- ize that failure to distribute widely the profits of industry has been a prime cause of our present plight. But rightly or wrongly, many persons think that one of the major contributing causes has been unbridled competition. Increasingly, doubt is expressed whether it is economically wise or morally right, that men should be permitted to add to the producing facilities of an industry which is already suffering from over-capacity. In justification of that doubt, men point to the excess capacity of our productive facilities resulting from their vast ex- pansion without corresponding increase in the consumptive capacity of the people. They assert that through improved methods of manufacture, made possible by ad- vances in science and invention and vast accumulation of capital, our industries had become capable of producing from thirty to one hundred per cent more than was consumed even in the days of vaunted prosperity: and that the present capacity will, for a long time, exceed the needs of business. All agree that irregularity in employment -- the greatest of our evils — cannot be overcome unless produc- tion and consumption are more nearly balanced. Many insist there must be some form of economic control." % \ V 4 I 3. One of the fundamental weaknesses of voluntary action in restricting the quantity placed in the primary channels of trade is that non-participating indi- viduals derive the benefits of such action without bearing any of the burdens. Such individuals usually consider only their own self interest and do not con- sider the possibility of loss to themselves as well as to the industry as a whole if their lack of participation results in the demoralization and failure of industry-wide restriction programs. Experience has shown, that it takes only a small number of non-participating growers to greatly impair programs which aim to limit or curtail production or shipments. The failure of a few to participate induces other growers to desert the programs or at least to lose some of their enthusiasm. Therefore, it has been suggested that in order to obtain the desired control in curtailment programs, that benefits and costs be prorated equitably among all growers in the industry by making participation in a restriction pro- gram compulsory if two-thirds or more of the growers desire to engage in such action and if such compulsion is essential to the welfare of the industry. PROPOSALS FOR EFFECTING PRORATION Three possible administrative set-ups for making supply limitation effec- tive have been mentioned and considered by persons interested in production or marketing restrictions. First, the production and marketing of certain agricul- tural crops might be made public utilities; that is, it might be shown that public welfare was sufficiently involved to justify the fixing of the prices, the volume of production, and the number of producers and handlers, and the maximum profits in the same manner as the gas and electric and railroad companies and other public utilities are regulated. Second, it might be made mandatory for all producers to market through one marketing agency, this agency to be grower owned and controlled. The products would then be sold through one organization which would have authority, in periods of excessive supplies, to divert a part to by- products or allow a part to remain unharvested. At the end of the marketing season the proceeds from the quantity sold would be divided among the growers on an equitable basis. Third, it has been suggested that a governmental agency be set up to determine the quantity to be placed in the primary channels of trade and that this quantity be prorated among all the growers in a fair manner; par- ticipation in the proration to be compulsory if two-thirds of the producers of a specified commodity desired to participate in such action. There are several important differences between the three proposals. Under a compulsory proration program the marketing of the products is left in the hands of existing agencies. Growers may sell their crops through any agency they wish, at any place, and for any price that they care to accept. The only restriction, except with some perishable commodities the production of which is highly seasonal and where the time of shipment or delivery would be regulated, is on the volume of shipments or deliveries with the view of receiving a greater net return for the whole industry than by marketing the entire quantity produced. On the other hand, a compulsory marketing program would mean that a single marketing agency would have complete authority over all phases of the elementary marketing process. Under public utility status, the number of producers or the number of handlers of specific commodities or both the number of producers and handlers would be re- stricted, the prices to be charged would be fixed and profits limited. It is doubtful whether at the present time either the application of public utility status to producers and handlers of agricultural commodities or compulsory Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2014 https://archive.org/details/economiclegalasp22stok 4. marketing would be held constitutional. Recent decisions indicate that the courts are not favorable toward broadening the field of industries to be classed as public utilities.^ A case that arose in Oklahoma shows their present position. The state of Oklahoma, in 1925, enacted a statute which forbade any person en- gaging in the ice business without first obtaining a license from the Corporation Commission. The Commission was specifically authorized to deny applications for a license if the existing licensed facilities were sufficient to meet the public needs. The Corporation Commission was further authorized to determine the prices at which ice might be offered for sale. The Supreme Court held the Oklahoma statute unconstitutional under the 14th Amendment of the Federal Constitution. The court said (in part), "There is nothing in the product that we can perceive on which to rest a distinction, in respect of this attempted control, from other products in common use which enter into free competition, subject, of course, to reasonable regulation prescribed for the protection of the public and applied with appropriate impartiality."^ Aside from the opposition of the courts toward the extension of the field of public utilities, a question arises as to the feasibility of accomplishing the objective of shipment restriction under public utility regulation unless such regulation were accompanied by authority for proration. For example, even though the acreage and the number of producers of vine and tree crops were limited, climatic variations from year to year would cause variations in production. Then in years of large crops or low consumer purchasing power, prices would be low un- less there was restriction on the quantity marketed. In addition, public utility regulation of production would raise numerous complex administrative problems. Compulsory marketing through a single agency or under the direction of a governmental agency has been undertaken in several countries including England, Australia and South Africa, all of which have a constitutional organization that permits such legislation without raising the question of constitutionality. In Canada, however, where governmental structure is similar to that of the United States, compulsory marketing has been held unconstitutional. The Canadian courts in February, 1931 declared the "Produce Marketing Act" to be ultra vires (un- constitutional) of the Provincial Legislature. Under the Produce Marketing Act, as amended in 1930, all shippers, proprietary or cooperative, were obliged to turn over to the committee of direction copies of all invoices for fruit sold. \/ New State Ice Co. vs. Liebmann — 52 S C f 371 - 1932; a like decision in Bourland Ice Co. vs. Franklin Utilities Co. 22 S W (2d) 993. 1929. ^Numerous other cases show that the courts are opposed to extending the field of public utilities. Williams vs. Standard Oil of Louisiana. 278 U S 239. 1929. Chas. Wolff Packing Co. vs. Court of Industrial Relations. 262 US 522. 1923. John F. Jelke vs. Emery. 193 Wis. 311. 1927. Fairmont Creamery Co. vs. Minnesota. 274 U S 1. 1927. Adams vs. Turner. 244 U S 590. 1917. 5. It was intended that the prices received for all fruit of the same grade and variety should be averaged and all expenses for freight, storage, and special packing for foreign shipments be deducted from the pool. Each grower contri- buting the same grade of fruit in the pools would be paid the same amount for his fruit regardless of whether it was sold on the domestic or foreign market, or was sold in season or after storage. Although compulsory marketing through one agency has not been attempted in this country, the nearest analogy indicates that it would not be upheld by the courts. The United States Supreme Court held the Oregon Compulsory Edu- cation Act, which when practically construed required all normal children be- tween the ages of 8 and 16 to attend public schools, to be in violation of the 14th Amendment of the Federal Constitution in that it deprived parents and children of their rights in the matter of the selection of schools. Such an act might be looked upon as compulsory education through a single agency. If such action is contrary to the Federal Constitution, it is probable that com- pulsory marketing of agricultural products through one agency would likewise be held unconstitutional whether enacted by state or federal statute. In view of the foregoing decisions concerning the status of public util- ity regulation and compulsory marketing and the fact (as is shown below) that compulsory proration has been considered more favorably by the courts, attention from this point will be centered upon it. During the oast seven years (1925-1932) the producers of several specialty crops have undertaken voluntary proration in marketing. The lemon growers, the Imperial Valley lettuce and cantaloupe growers, the Watsonville apple growers, and the Valencia orange growers have attempted voluntary proration in shipments. The cling peach growers and the grape growers, through the California Grape Con- trol Board, have attempted other methods in restricting the volume marketed in the primary channels of trade. A summary of these attempts is made in pages 12 to 19. PROBABLE LEGAL STATUS OF PRORATION IN AGRICULTURAL MARKETING The R ule of Reason .-- Although it is impossible to forecast a decision of the courts on a specific proposal, such as compulsory proration of the shioments of agricultural products, one may ascertain the attitude of the courts toward the control of economic activities through a review of their decisions. As far as we know there has been no judicial review in which the legality of the proration of the marketing of agricultural products entered into volun- tarily by growers has been a specific point, but we may infer that, if such practices do not enhance prices beyond a reasonable return to the producer and if they are temporary measures in the face of economic necessity for the well- being of an industry, they would be considered within the rule of reason by the J^ the United States Supreme Court said: "Certainly the statute (Kentucky Cooperative Marketing Act) impaired no right of the ware- house company guaranteed by the 14th Amendment by merely authorizing corpor- ations with membership limited to agriculturists and permitting contracts for ourchase and resale of farm products. This is also true of the declaration that such associations shall not be deemed monopolies, combinations or conspiracies in restraint of trade and that contracts with members shall not be illegal." In this same decision the court went further in declaring its attitude toward collective action of farmers by saying: "If restrictions on production are to be accomplished by voluntary agreements entered into pursuant to statutes author- izing them there would be no objection thereto from a state or a federal stand- point unless a state statute was construed as authorizing what was forbidden by a federal act. A state or federal government is undoubtedly free to declare what its public policy shall be in matters of this kind." 17 The lower courts./ in passing upon the same case summarized succinctly the present attitude of the courts toward group effort on the part of agricultural producers in the following: "public policy does not ask those who till the soil to take less than a fair return for their labor. Public policy safeguards society from oppression; it is not an instrument of oppression." Proration in Oil Revie wed by Courts.-- Several decisions involving com- pulsory proration of oil indicate that the compulsory proration of agricultural products would be looked upon favorably by the courts. In the states of Okla- homa and Texas compulsory proration of oil production has been in effect for several years. The legality of this procedure was tested in the lower courts and came before the United States Supreme Court in the Champlin Refining Co. vs. xZLiberty Warehouse Co. vs. Burley Tobacco Growers Cooperative Assn. 276 U S 71. 1927. VySee also Rifle Potato Growers vs. Smith (78 Colo. 171)., 1925, giving agri- culturists right to make contracts for cooperative marketing: held not violative of the Constitution as class legislation. "The legislature may reasonably classify for the purpose of legislation, and a law is not local or special when it is general and uniform in its operation upon all in a like situation." An interesting contrast in the present and earlier attitude of the courts tov-iard cooperative marketing organizations will be obtained by comparing the foregoing decision with Georgia Fruit Exchange vs. Turnipseed (1910), 9 Ala. App. 123; 62 So. 542 where it was held that an agreement to take a share of stock in an association to market fruit which contemplated handling at least sixty per cent of the fruit grown in the state was invalid. ij' Liberty Warehouse Co. vs. Burley Tobacco Growers Cooperative Assn. (Ky. 1925) 2 71 S W 695. the Corporation Commission of Oklahoma in May, 1932. The Supreme Court upheld the statute of the state of Oklahoma under which the Corporation Commission was given the power to prorate the amount of oil that each producer from a given field might take therefrom in order to prevent un- necessary loss and waste. A few of the restricted oil companies contended that they had been deprived of their legal rights without due process of law and therefore such production limitations by the state were unconstitutional. How- ever, the proration activities by these states have been upheld by the courts on the grounds that the public has sufficient interest to justify reasonable legis- lation under the "police power". ^ The court said: "It is common knowledge that petroleum products have become indispensible not only to railroads but also to automobile travel. Inhabitants of the cities are dependent upon natural gas for fuel. Also a large acreage of land set aside for educational purposes con- tains large oil deposits. In addition, taxes derived from oil production now constitute a large part of the state's revenue. These facts emphasize the im- portance of conservation of these resources for the general welfare of the people ." It must be recognized, however, that the courts have pointed out in their decisions concerning oil proration that the purpose of curtailment was not to unduly enhance the market price of oil, but to conserve a natural resource. In the case of the MacMillan vs. the Railroad Commission of Texas20/the court said: "The policy of artificial forcing of prices by government action in cooperation with the oil industry by either stimulating demand or keeping supply in bounds has never been attempted by the legislature itself and has been forbidden by positive penal laws...." At the same time, however, the courts recognized the effect of curtailment on prices by stating that although the curtailment of production tended incident- ally to enhance the price of petroleum, it was not sufficient evidence to invali- date the proration order. The language of the court in the Danziger oil case emphasizes this point: "The Commission has no authority to issue an order which had for its purpose the control or regulation of economic conditions, or which was designed to affect prices or to prevent economic waste but such limitation is not a denial to the Commission of the power to take into consideration an economic standard, or economic conditions, if such conditions bear a direct or reasonable relationship to physical waste." The court in the Champlin Refining case-xValso pointed out: "If the statute enforced as it has been by the com- Champlin Refining Co. vs. Corporation Commission of Oklahoma. 286 U S 210. 1932. •ix Danziger Oil and Refining Co. vs. Texas R. R. Commission. 49 S W (2d) 837. 1932. §9^ MacMillan vs. Railroad Commission of Texas 51 F (2d) 400, 1931. See also Peoples Petroleum Co. vs. Smith. 1. Fed. Sup. 400, 1932. Sterling vs. Constantin 53 S W 190. 1932. Champlin Refining Co. vs. Corporation Commission of Oklahoma. 286 U S 210. 1932. 10. mission strictly in accordance with legislative intent has incidentally tended to promote the prosperity of the oil industry in Oklahoma, or of the state generally, or to prevent economic demoralization, it is not to be condemned but rather upheld for that reason." The foregoing decision would seem to put the court on record as justify- ing proration from the standpoint of preventing physical waste; however, there is definite recognition of the fact that it is desirable to prevent economic waste. One may inquire concerning the difference between physical and economic waste whereupon he encounters the difficulty of drawing a fine distinction. There are several forms of waste, i.e., waste in consumption (vice, crime, harm- ful drugs), waste of man power (unemployment), waste in the technique of pro- duction and distribution, and waste of produced and natural resources. They all involve economic waste and physical waste. The degree of physical waste or the degree of economic waste in each case is incalculable, yet either one may appear more important than the other at a particular time or place. For example, certain timber which rots and decays in the forests is looked upon as a physical waste at the point of oroduction. In cities this same timber would be valuable for fuel, if for nothing else, and it would be considered an economic waste to allow the timber to rot there. The principal reason for the change in point of view is that at the point of production the timber is valueless but in the cities it has a definite value. In numerous California agricultural industries there is likely to be a high degree of physical waste as well as economic waste whether or not some de- gree of control is exercised over the volume marketed. During the past year (1932) a considerable volume of several specialty crops was unharvested because prices at the point of production were so low that it would not pay to harvest them. In fact, producers of several crops found themselves indebted to trans- portation agencies at the end of the marketing season because their products did not sell for enough in terminal markets to pay the freight. The uncertainty caused by such a situation probably resulted in both a larger physical and econ- omic waste than would have occurred if definite steps had been taken to market limited quantities during each week of the shioping season and prorate such marketings among all producers. When no restriction is placed upon marketings each individual hopes to market as much as possible before a drastic fall in prices occurs. When the inevitable crash comes nearly all growers cease market- ing. Prices again recover and then shipments are again forwarded in excessive volume and another price decline ensues when they reach destination. In the meantime, considerable quantities go out of condition or spoil, both at the point of production and in terminal markets. Legistic Theories Justifying Proration .-- The legistic theory upon which the proration of oil came before the courts in the Champlin Refining case was under the police power which reserves to the government the right to exercise restrictions upon individuals or groups in the welfare of society as a whole. The proration of oil has also been reviewed by the courts under the legistic con- ception of the protection of the co-relative rights of individuals within a group. In Bandini Oil Co. vs. Superior Courts it was held that the state could U .DO freight and icing 1 Price after de- ducting ^0.30 iUI pXCK-JLIlg, packing, load- ing, 'and hauling Probable total re- O U.I lib UI1 the vines Carloads 882 lugs ! I Packages 31 pounds 1 2 3 4 S 6_ 7_ 3,500 3,087,000 11.54 $1,432 #0.782 |0.482 #1,567,934 4,000 3,528,000 1.38 1.273 0.623 0.323 1,139,544 4,500 3,969,000 1.26 1.172 0.522 0.222 981,118 5,000 4,410,000 1.15 1.069 0.419 0.119 524,790 5,500 4,851,000 1.06 0.986 0.336 0.036 174,636 6,000 5,292,000 0.98 0.911 0.261 -0.029 -153,468 6,500 5, 733,000 0.90 0.837 0.187 -0.113 -647.829 7,000 6, 174,000 0.83 0.772 0.122 -0.178 -1,098,972 * Assuming shipments of California table grapes (other than Tokays and Emperors) at 11,000 carloads and the index of wholesale prices at 65. Source of data: Study of the marketing of Tokay grapes. Giannini Foundation. Unpublished . The returns which might have been expected by shipping the quantities shown in column 2 were calculated as follows. An analysis of the factors affect- ing annual delivered prices for Tokay grapes was made.^9-'' From this analysis an estimate was made of the probable average annual delivered price for Tokay grapes in 1932 with the shipment of quantities shown in column 2. Deductions were made from the delivered selling price for harvesting, packing, transportation, and selling costs as shown in columns 4, 5, and 6. The prices shown in column 6 are then the net prices for grapes on the vines which growers might have expected by marketing the quantities shown in column 2. A comparison of columns 1 and 7 shows that under 1932 conditions the total returns to growers would decrease as the volume of shipments increased- It also shows that the shipment of a quantity in excess of 5,500 carloads would be likely x/ Stokdyk, E. A. Factors affecting annual Tokay grape prices. Blue Anchor. 9:7:2. July, 1932. 14. to result in losses from marketing. In other words, growers would not receive harvesting and marketing costs. The last two items in' column 7 may appear ex- treme for it may be argued that growers would not continue to harvest and market their grapes if the costs incurred in these operations were not recovered. It is probable that growers would cease harvesting if delivered prices were con- stantly low; however, delivered prices during the season fluctuate considerably. A period of 10 days to two weeks elapses before shipments from California reach eastern markets. Prevailing prices often induce growers to ship heavily but when the shipments reach destination, severe price declines are experienced. The result is that at times growers do not recover harvesting and marketing costs and in some cases not enough to cover transportation expenses. Studies of the relationships between shipments and prices of several other California commodities show a similar situation, namely that a greater output will not compensate for a lower price per unit, and that in some cases the market ing of the entire quantity produced results in direct losses to growers, prevails in several California agricultural industries .^V The foregoing situation has led to attempts on the part of growers to re- strict the total quantity marketed in the primary channels of trade. In order, hOY/ever, to exert much influence on the quantity marketed in these channels there must be a control of a large part, if not the whole, of the supply. Such control is possible in the case of many California products, because numerous crops are produced almost exclusively within the state. The possibility of increasing total returns by restricting supplies varies however, from commodity to commodity. The perishability of the product, the size of the market area, the probability of substitutes taking the place of the com- modity in question, the probability of production expanding in other areas, and the elasticity of demand are factors which influence it. It is not the purpose of this study to analyze these factors in detail. Such factors usually have been given careful consideration before prorate programs were undertaken. The follow- ing record of voluntary prorate programs will show the influence of some of them and bring out some of the problems involved in such programs. Pror ation of Lemon Shipments .-- California lemon producers have pioneered in shipment proration. As early as 1925 the quantity of lemons produced in re- lation to the existing demand was such that if all the crop were marketed fresh, prices would be unremunerative to the majority of the growers. In several years since then, a quantity of lemons has been diverted from the fresh market to by- products with the result that total returns to growers have been increased. At the present time, about 25 per cent of the crop is so diverted. This procedure v / Shear, S. W. California Bartlett pear situation. Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. Mimeo. Dec. 15, 1932. Also Wellman, H. R. Some aspects of surplus control with particular reference to the summer orange indus- try of California. Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. Mimeo. January, 1933. 15. is possible because lemon growers market approximately 90 per cent of the crop through one selling agency, The California Fruit Growers Exchange, which holds contracts with its members to apportion the quantity each is to sell in the pri- mary channels of trade. Each week of the marketing season an estimate is made of the number of carloads of lemons to be shipped which will result in a reason- able price to the producers and consumers. Each member of the Exchange is then allotted his proportion of the total number of carloads on the basis of the quantity of lemons he has in his packing and storage sheds. The principal diffi- culties encountered are (l) the unrestricted shipments of non-members of the Ex- change, and (2) the problem of forecasting the quantity to be marketed each week which will result in reasonable prices. The first difficulty is one which is inherent in all voluntary restriction programs. It is a difficulty which com- pulsory proration aims to overcome. Non-participating growers who ship the en- tire quantity which they produce in the primary channels of trade gain benefits from the restriction program at the expense of the participating members; they take more than an equitable share of the market opportunity. The second diffi- culty is one which would be encountered in compulsory prorate programs as well as voluntary prorate programs. This can be and is being met by an analysis of the factors affecting seasonal prices and by combining the experience and judg- ment of experienced dealers and handlers. It is important to remember that this difficulty will always be present. There will be conflict of opinion concerning the exact quantity to be marketed, mistakes will be made, and those who are not in sympathy with proration programs or the administration of such programs will emphasize mistakes of such a nature. Valencia Orange Proration.-- Unlike lemons, the supply of Valencia oranges in relation to existing demand has usually resulted in prices remuner- ative to the majority of the producers. However, early in 1932 indications were that the California Valencia orange crop in relation to the low purchasing pov^er of consumers was such that if all the crop were marketed fresh, prices to growers would be extremely low.££'' A Valencia orange proration agreement among the grow- ers selling through the seven largest shipping organizations was prepared and effected on June 19, 1932. It was agreed to determine from week to week the num- ber of carloads of Valencia oranges during the 1932 Valencia shipping season which could be sold at reasonable prices and to prorate between the parties to the agreement this total number of cars on the basis that the percentage of fruit controlled by each signer of the agreement bore to the total amount of the fruit yet to be shipped as of the date June 15, 1932. This agreement was in effect approximately thirty days. The prices of oranges in auction markets advanced steadily throughout the time the agreement was in effect and when the prorate ended prices were 55 cents a box higher than when the prorate started. However, after operating for a month, the agreement was terminated because s*/ Valencia proration agreement fails. Orange County Farm Bureau News. 15: 8. August, 1932. 16. of the withdrawal of two of the shipping organizations. It has been estimated that if this plan had remained in operation the remainder of the season and if the price during the last week of the program had been maintained, the returns to Valencia growers would have been increased by approximately $4, 000, 000. The withdrawal of two shipping organizations led to its abandonment. This action destroyed the limited market opportunity for the whole group. The majority of the producers were willing to conduct the program but a minority were responsi- ble for its cessation. Tokay Grape Prorate.-" The growers of Tokay grape s^^" in San Joaquin County, California, conducted a voluntary proration program in 1932. They had witnessed a crop of 7,670 carloads sell for an average delivered price of $1 .14 per package in 1930 while in 1931, a year of low production, 4,109 carloads were shipped with a resulting price of $1.59 per package. This meant that the large crop of 7,670 carloads in 1930 netted the growers approximately .|750,000, while the much smaller crop in 1931 netted more than $2,000,000. The 1932 season promised to be another large crop year and the purchasing power of the consumers was known to be less than in the two previous years. The analysis presented in table 1 indicated that the shipment of the entire crop of Tokays would result in marketing losses. The growers and shippers realizing the seriousness of the situation organized a shipment restriction plan. The plan adopted was that of rating the productive capacity of each grower's vineyard and allotting shipments on the basis of the percentage that each grower's rating was of the total rated capacity of all vineyards. The Tokay proration program was conducted without contracts with growers or marketing agencies. It was in effect for four weeks, then abandoned because non-participating growers and shippers marketed increasing quantities as the participating growers and shippers restricted the quantities they marketed. The Tokay prorate demonstrated, however, that prices for this variety of grape would respond to the volume marketed and that returns to growers could be increased by restricting the quantity marketed. Lettuce P roration. — The Imperial Valley lettuce growers have at times prorated their shipments since 1929. This valley furnishes a very large part of the winter lettuce for the United States and this lettuce is grown by about 70 firms or individuals who plant all the way from 50 to 3,500 acres each. The pro- ration of shipments is conducted under the direction of a clearing house associ- ation. Each shipper signs an agreement giving the secretary of the clearing house authority to order empty cars from the railroad. By so doing the clearing house can regulate the number of carloads that are to be shipped from the Imperial Valley on a given day. The proration is based on the acreage the ship- per has, the number of carloads he has shipped up to the time the prorate goes into effect and the yield per acre. Proration of lettuce shipments is not oper- 33/ Report of the Valencia Prorate Committee. California Citrograph, 17: 10. August, 1932. Wellman, H. R. Factors affecting orange prices and economics of surplus control. California Citrograph, 17: 7. May, 1932. Stokdyk,. E. A. An experiment in surplus control. Blue Anchor. 10: 1: 6. January, 1933. ... • j 17. ative, however, until it is apparent that the volume of shipments is likely to be such as will result in extremely low prices. The lettuce proration programs have been conducted with little friction through voluntary action. The area is small, the number of growers comparatively few, and the growers are mostly grower-dealers who have had wide experience in the growing and handling of the crop. However, some difficulty is encountered in effecting the prorate programs with growers who are inexperienced. Cantaloupe P ro ratio n.-- In 1932-O'the Imperial Valley cantaloupe gro?«/ers were confronted with a' large crop and low consumer purchasing power. A clearing house comparable to that of the lettuce growers was organized. The clearing house limited shipments by prorating on the basis of each shipper's daily pack- ings in relation to the total quantity which the clearing house decided should be marketed. The results of this program were that large losses were avoided which would have been incurred if the entire crop had been marketed. Watsonville Apple Prorate. — During the 1930-31 season the Watsonville apple growers and shippers had such a quantity of apples in storage that if no restriction were placed on the quantity withdrawn at a given time prices would be extremely low throughout the marketing period. An agreement was made among those having apples in storage to limit the quantity withdrawn from storage each week and to prorate the quantity each grower and shipper was to market on the relation which the quantity he held in storage bore to the total quantity in storage at the beginning of the prorate period. This action resulted in an in- crease in price of nearly $10 per ton. The following year, however, when a simi- lar situation confronted the Watsonville growers and shippers, it was impossible to obtain similar action because a few who had not participated in 1931 had re- ceived benefits at the expense of the participants. Canning Peach Limitation Prog ram. — The California cling peach growers restricted the quantity canned in 1930 and 19 31 through a program whereby the limited quantity canned was assessed to establish a fund to indemnify some pro- ducers for not harvesting their crops. The unharvested crop was appraised for quantity and quality and growers were compensated accordingly. This procedure was effective in reducing the quantity canned to a point where canners were will- ing to pay a small sum per ton for the portion canned. The experiences of the 1930 and 1931 curtailment programs showed that some savings could be made by appraising the crops that were to remain unharvested early in the season and thus avoid the expense of bringing them to maturity. In 1932-J3"' a plan was proposed which called for the buying of some fruit at thinning time instead of at maturity and the reduction of acreage approximating x3/ Jaekson, W. L. Controlling shipments helps cantaloupe deal. California Cultivator. 79: 6. August 6, 1932. 36/ Slash peach production. Western Canner and Packer, p. 5. 24; 1. May, 1932. 18. 20 per cent by tree removal. It was estimated that the earlier allotment of pro- duction would save growers approximately $3 per ton in irrigation, care, and thinning expense. In addition, growers who agreed to cut off or remove their trees before the crop reached maturity were to be oaid $4 per ton based on the average tonnage of number one peaches produced during the 1930 and 1931 seasons. It was expected that such a payment would induce growers to remove a larger acre- age than would be removed if no payments were made and that the cost of compen- sating the growers would not exceed greatly the cost of buying the same fruit. This plan failed to get the necessary support from all factors, hence there was no planned limitation of the quantity canned in 1932. Although most of the canners and growers were willing to participate in the curtailment program and some growers marketed only half of their crops, a number of canners declined to participate in the crop curtailment and certain groups of growers developed their entire crop for delivery to such canners. These groups no doubt antici- pated that they could market their full crop without carrying a share of the cur- tailment. As a result, the curtailment program was not effected and gro¥\rers re- ceived only $6.50 per ton (barely enough to cover their harvesting costs) for the fruit delivered to canners and nothing for the portion which was unharvested, whereas in 1931 growers received $14.50 a ton for fruit delivered to canneries and $9.00 per ton for the unharvested tonnage. California Grape Control Board Operations.-- Similar to that of the can- ning peach limitation, a program was attempted by the California grape grov^ers in 1930. The quantity marketed by growers signing the contracts was assessed and the funds so received were used to purchase the quantities in excess of the normal requirements. The control organization attempted to dispose of some of the excess in the form of by-products. The control was conducted during the 1930 and 1931 seasons but abandoned in 1932. <§s Several factors brought on its abandonment. Some growers failed to fulfill their contracts. Insufficient funds were available to purchase the quantities of all varieties of grapes which were in excess of normal market re- quirements. The by-products did not return as much as was originally antici- pated. In addition, it was found that table, raisin, and juice grapes differed so widely in use and in method of marketing that administrative problems were extremely complicated. Summary of Prorati on Attempts.-- The foregoing prorate programs have demonstrated that with some commodities returns to producers can be increased by restricting the quantities marketed in the primary channels of trade. At the same time, it is significant that none of these restrictions has been attacked as being contrary to public policy on the grounds that they unduly enhanced prices to consumers. 37 Peach control fails. Western Canner and Packer, p. 16. 24: 4. Aug., 1932 California Canning Peach Growers -- Eleventh Annual Report. Dec. 6, 1932. 38/ In 1930 considerable quantities of grapes were unharvested and paid for as in the cling peach control. In 1931 when the vine crops were small no control of this kind was undertaken. 19. Each of the programs mentioned was undertaken only when it was obvious that returns to growers would be extremely low or severe losses would be in- curred in harvesting and marketing if all of the crops were marketed in the primary channels of trade. It is doubtful whether growers would undertake pro- rate programs if it were probable that returns would be sufficient to cover much more than cash costs of production and marketing because of the fear that pro- rate programs under such circumstances would be likely to stimulate plantings. Each of the foregoing programs encountered the difficulty of obtaining and maintaining participation by a large proportion of the growers. Numerous growers who have participated in such programs recognize the economic gains to the industry yet refuse to participate again unless all growers participate. This situation has lead many to believe that it is desirable to make partici- pation compulsory for all growers if two-thirds or more of the growers are will- ing to conduct a restriction program. PROBLEMS OF ADMINISTRATION OF COMPULSORY PRORATE PROGRAMS The principal administrative problem in compulsory prorate programs would be to adjust equitably benefits and burdens among all parties concerned. Other problems would be: (l) determining an industry's desire for such a program, (2) determining the extent to which to prorate or the volume to market, and (3) financing and enforcing the program. Determining an Industry's Desire for Proration.-- There would be a diffi- culty, as is the case with any democratic expression of opinion, in ascertaining the attitude of growers toward proration. Although the activities of a few en- thusiastic individuals might seem to indicate that a prorate program had the sup- port of the majority, there would be a possibility of unorganized opposition. This difficulty could be overcome by submitting the question of compulsory pro- ration to the qualified growers through election or by asking the sponsors to obtain signatures to a petition. The positive endorsement of two-thirds of the growers should be reasonable assurance of a desire on their part for a prorate program. In this respect the action would follow precedent in matters of great importance where more definite expression of opinion than a majority expression was desired. The foregoing procedure might be conducted under the supervision of a duly appointed commission. Determining the Extent to Prorate.-- If the producers of a specified com- modity were in favor of compulsory proration, the next problem which would arise is that of determining the extent to which to prorate or the volume to market. The commission referred to above might appoint representatives from within the industry requesting compulsory proration to determine the quantity to be marketed and to formulate the procedure for prorating this quantity among growers, the actions of such representatives to be subject to the approval of the commission. Such a procedure would give assurance that experienced judgment would be avail- able when a specific program is undertaken. Distribution of Benefits and Burdens .-- The determination of the method of proration to distribute benefits and burdens equitably is a problem that would need most careful consideration in each industry which contemplated such action. 20. One of the principal factors which would influence the method of pro- rating would be the possibility of disposing of the quantity which would not be placed in the primary channels of trade. If it were possible to market this quantity in the form of by-products at prices which would return harvesting ex- penses, proration might be made on the basis of the total quantity delivered to marketing agencies or on the quantity sold in secondary channels. On the other hand, if harvesting costs could not be recouped on the quantity marketed as by- products, proration might be made on the basis of each grower's normal produc- tion. Another factor which would influence the method of prorating of fruits and vegetables would be the distribution of the production and the quantity of various grades and sizes. The marketings in primary trade channels might be re- stricted to first grades and/or larger sizes. Such a method might be feasible and equitable if the production of the lower grades and sizes were fairly well distributed among all growers and if the quantity in excess of the amount which an industry desired to eliminate from the primary channels of trade coincided with the quantity of lower grades and sizes. However, if there is wide vari- ation in grades and sizes among producers and if the quantity which had to be eliminated from the primary channels to obtain reasonable prices were far in excess of the quantity of lower grades and sizes, such a method of proration would be unlikely to gain the support of the majority of the producers. For ex- ample, if it were apparent that only half of a specified crop (as was the case with Tokay grapes in 1932) could be marketed at prices which would return more than harvesting and marketing expenses, a considerable portion of the best quali- ty would have to remain unharvested if shipments were restricted to one-half of the crop. If a large portion of the growers were not producing crops at least half of which were of best quality, they would oppose a restriction program which would permit only the growers of the best quality to market any portion of their crops . A third factor would be the degree of perishability of the crop. If it were possible to store the commodity, proration might be made on the quantity packed and held in storage, whereas if the commodity were highly perishable it would be impracticable to adopt such a method of prorating. A fourth factor would be the period of time covered by the prorate and whether the crop were annual or perennial. The most feasible procedure with perennial crops, v/here a prorate program was to apply for a period of three or four years, might be to prorate on the basis of the average production for previous years. Then each grower could abandon a portion of his acreage and not incur the expense of bringing that portion of his acreage to maturity each year; or he could remove a portion of his acreage from cultivation. On the other hand, with some annual crops the proration might be made on an acreage basis in advance of planting time. In addition to the problem of the method of prorating, other problems would arise in connection with distributing benefits and burdens equitably, such as the extent to which restriction should be employed during short oeriods of time, and, in the case of highly perishable commodities, the problem of whether to prorate on the basis of the amount of the product remaining to be marketed when the restriction becomes effective or on the basis of the total tonnage pro- duced. For example, it might be advisable to restrict shipments to a greater 21. extent early in the season than late in the season because of seasonal changes in demand. If so, the problem of making adjustments between those producers whose crops were early and those whose crops were late would arise. On the other hand, it might not be necessary to restrict shipments early in the season because the volume available for marketing early might be small. Then the question arises whether or not to count the early shipments as a portion of the individual grow- er's allotment or to exclude them from individual proration calculations. Each of the foregoing problems would have to be considered and decided in the light of the circumstances peculiar to each industry. The experience and judgment of those within the industry would have to be relied upon in this con- nection. It is probable, however, that no matter what method of proration were adopted or how equitably a proration program were conducted, some growers would contend that they had been treated unequitably. This situation is inherent in any attempts to restrict or regulate individuals in the interest of the entire group; it is common to all phases of regulation. Growers should anticipate some inequalities and weigh these against the probable returns they would receive if there were no regulations. Enforcement . — In order to facilitate enforcement of a prorate program, certificates might be issued to each producer which stated the quantity^- and the time each producer should market his proportion of the total quantity to be marketed. It might also be made unlawful for any producer to deliver to any dealer, or for any dealer or handler to have in his possession, within the state, any commodity upon which a prorate program has been instituted without an ac- companying certificate issued under authority of the prorate commission. Any person xvho violated any provision of a prorate program might also be enjoined in action brought in the superior court for the county in which the violation is alleged to have occurred. Financing . -- The financing of prorate programs might be accomplished by collecting fees for the certificates referred to above. Some degree of assur- ance that the expenses of conducting a specific prorate would not be excessive would be given if each program were made self-sustaining; that is, if provision were made that each would be financed by the industry requesting it. This re- quirement would impel serious consideration on the part of those who sponsored a program for a particular industry. In fact, the probable cost of administering a prorate program might in some cases preclude its initiation. If a program were under way, it would be in the interest of every participant to assist rather than to hinder enforcement in order to keep the expense of administration at a minimum. APPRAISAL OF THE DESIRABILITY AMD FEASIBILITY OF PRORATE PROGRAMS The principal question which arises in connection with the desirability of prorate programs is whether such action is preferable to allowing the long-time \7 It is possible that in some situations the exact quantity each producer would be entitled to market during a specific period of time could not be stated on the certificates far in advance of the inauguration of a prorate program. Certificates might show each producer's share as a percentage of the total quan- tity to be marketed during designated periods. 22. effect of low returns to producers of certain commodities such as tree and vine crops to bring about a reduction in production. The latter procedure is one to which numerous persons subscribe. It is argued that in the long run the func- tion of price is to control production: consequently attempts to restrict market- ings go contrary to long-run forces and operate to destroy the tendency of econ- omic forces to reach equilibrium. The first part of the argument is generally accepted. However, there is serious question regarding the second part. If the variations in prices of agricultural commodities were caused primarily by the volume of production, the most economical way (assuming that costs of production and marketing were at an irreducible minimum and that it was impracticable to attempt to increase demand) to bring remunerative returns to growers of perennial crops and at the same time assist in bringing about equilibrium of economic forces would be to reduce the production of the crop in question. Since 1929 one of the principal factors influencing prices has been the low purchasing power of consumers. If it is agreed that their purchasing power will increase in the future (as it has done after previous periods of depression), it would be un- economical to reduce the production of many perennial crops to meet the present low purchasing power conditions. Such a reduction of production would be carried too far for periods of higher purchasing power and then plantings would be likely to be unduly stimulated. The ultimate result would be large capital losses and an unbalancing of economic forces. For this reason, it appears desirable to pro- rate the marketings of some perennial crops to meet the situation which confronts numerous California agricultural industries. With annual crops, the production of which can be expanded or contracted fairly easily through an increase or decrease in acreage, the logical procedure is to attempt to adjust acreage to existing demand. A planned adjustment such as the proration of acreage before planting has several advantages over un- planned adjustment because experience has shown that the majority of producers are influenced in their adjustments by prevailing prices rather than prospective prices. 'I9' Adjustments of acreage prior to planting, whether planned or unplanned, could not, however, bring about a perfect adjustment in production because the volume of production is influenced by factors other than acreage. For this reason it may be desirable to restrict the quantity marketed in primary channels, as has been done in the Imperial Valley with lettuce and cantaloupes, in seasons when supplies are excessive in relation to the existing demand. Such restriction must, however, be exercised with extreme caution with annual crops because if carried to a point where production is highly profitable in years of short crops and where losses are avoided in such years, acreage is likely to increase rapidly. That prorate programs to meet emergency situations are desirable has been the concensus of opinion of numerous groups; this is evidenced by the several voluntary attempts. The question of the desirability of making such programs compulsory, in the event that a large proportion of the producers of a particular commodity desires to engage in them, is another matter. The question brings to a ii/Bean, L. H. The farmers' response to price. Journal of Farm Economics . 9:3:368-395. July, 1929. Also Smith, Bradford B. Forecasting the acreage of cotton. Journal of American Statistical Association 20: 31-47. 1925. Stokdyk, E. A. Some factors influencing the mid-season potato market. Kansas State College of Agriculture and Applied Science. Tech. Bui. 28:26-28. 1931. 23. focus a subject of continual controversy in the history of the United States; namely, the degree which it is desirable for the government to regulate and control individuals in the interest of society as a whole. Strenuous arguments are raised against the extension of governmental control. It is held by some that governmental action impairs individual rights and is susceptible to undue favoritism. It is also contended that there is the possibility of political abuses.; furthermore, that it is difficult to ensure adequate supervision of governmental regulations. The foregoing difficulties are recognized by those who favor extension of the activities of government. However, they show that the trend of legal and economic thought has been toward control of individual economic activities be- cause the well-being of groups is of general concern and the group interest should, take precedence over the special interests of certain individuals. If compulsory proration operates to bring about general economic stability by in- creasing present returns to a particular industry without unduly enhancing prices to consumers, it should be favored. The unlimited freedom of action of a small minority is not sufficiently important to impair the progress of the whole group. A program in which participation is made compulsory by an act of the state legislature, organized for the purpose of limiting and prorating the quantity that might be placed on the market at any time, is not an unwarranted restriction on individual rights since it spreads the benefits and burdens on every grower in the particular industry. At the same time, there is reason to believe that there is sufficient public interest connected either directly or indirectly with the economic well-being of a particular industry to sanction group control. The long-run adjustment of agriculture will probably be left for the most part to the operation of economic forces. We may, however, seek to guide the operation of these forces in such a way as to minimize the hardships of the transition to a new point of equilibrium. The physicist does not repeal natural laws but has gone far in showing us how we can live with them in comfort. Through wise group control the producers of agricultural products may also seek to accommodate themselves to economic forces.^- The feasibility of voluntary prorate programs has been clearly established with some California agricultural commodities (see pages 12 to 19), and it is probable that prorate programs would be feasible with numerous products produced in California because many commodities are produced almost exclusively in this state. It would be impracticable, however, for California producers alone to attempt such programs with numerous products, such as wheat, cotton, barley, hogs, cattle, and -eggs, because their production is widely scattered throughout the United States and foreign countries. Similarly, it would be impracticable to limit marketings of products a considerable portion of which was produced in one or two other states without participation on the part of the producers in . ^p/The court in the Danziger Refining case (page 9) pointed out that the stability of a particular industry was of public interest. 43 t \S The Farm Relief Bill before Congress is an attempt to plan production to meet the existing situation in agriculture. 24. these states; for example, canning pears. The feasibility of compulsory prorate programs has not been demonstrated in agriculture but has been shown in certain areas in the oil industry. From experience in the latter industry it may be inferred that such programs would be feasible in the former industry. In fact, in some respects the administrative problem of distributing the benefits and burdens of prorate programs would be less complex in agriculture than in the oil industry. For example, the diffi- culty of making adjustments in the allotments of individuals because of an under ground flow of supply does not arise in agriculture. On the other hand, some phases of administration in agriculture are likely to be more complex because of the numerous trade channels through which the products move from producer to con sumer. In our view, however, the problems of compulsory proration in agricultur although complex, are not insurmountable. 25 SUMMARY The philosophy of proration is not new; it was manifested in the practices of the earlv English merchant and craft guilds , Each member was held to a "stint" or allotment to protect the limited market opportunity for all. Although the philosophy of unlimited competition was dominant in the Unit- ed States during the period of rapid development, now that we have developed a complex industrial structure and a specialized agriculture this philosophy is challenged. It is believed bv numerous persons that the new conditions call for control of competition with administration by groups as in the period of the guilds in England. A number of groups of agricultural producers have endeavored to limit com- petition bv restricting the volume marketed in the primary channels of trade in periods of excessive supplies or low consumer purchasing power or both. One of the fundamental weaknesses of their attem.pt s has been that non- participating pro- ducers derived : ore than an equitable share of the benefits of such action. This situation has caused abandonment of several of such programs, but has raised the question of the desirability and feasibility of making participation in them com- pulsory if the bulk of the producers desire to engage in shipment limitation and if such compulsion is essential to the welfare of the industry* Three distinct administrative set-ups have been proposed to make compul- sory restriction of shipments effective: (1) placing the production and market- ing of certain agricultural crops under public utility regulation, (2) making marketing through one agency mandatory, and ( 3 ) giving a governmental agency the power to administer proration programs. At the present time, it is probable that the courts would consider the third proposal more favorably than either the first or second. Although it is impossible to forecast a decision of the courts on a speci- fic proposal such as compulsory proration of the marketing of agricultural pro- ducts, we may infer from previous decisions if such a procedure does not enhance prices beyond a reasonable return to producers and if it is a temporary measure in the face of economic necessity, it will be considered within the rule of reason by the courts . The present position of legislative bodies and the courts toward attempts of farmers to improve their economic status is exceedingly liberal. Farmers' associations are no longer looked upon as monopolies, combinations, or conspirac- ies in restraint of trade and their contracts with members are binding. The Supreme Court has also stated that if restrictions on production are to be accom- plished bv voluntary agreements entered into pursuant to statutes authorizing them there is no objection thereto from a state or a federal standpoint. This court also declared that a state or federal government is free to declare what its public policy shall be in matters of this kind. Compulsory proration of oil production has been undertaken in Oklahoma and Texas. This action has been upheld bv the courts as reasonable exercise of the police power to conserve a natural resource. However, the court stated that if such action tended to promote the prosperity of the oil industry or of the statsi generally, or to prevent economic demoralization, it was not to be condemned but 26. rather upheld for that reason. This decision would seem to out the court on record as iustifving proration from the standpoint of preventing physical waste; however, it recognizes the desirability of preventing economic waste. In numerous California industries there is likely to be a high degree of physical waste as well as economic waste Whether or not some degree of control is exercised over the volume marketed. During the past year (1932) a considerable volume of several specialty crops was unharvested because prices at the point of production were so low that it would not pay toharvest them. In fact, producers of several crops found themselves indebted to transportation agencies at the end of the marketing season because their products did not sell for enough in terminal markets to pay the freight. The uncertainty caused by such a situation probably resulted in both a larger physical and economic waste than would have occurred if definite steps had been taken to market limited quantities during each week of the shipping season and prorate such marketings among all producers. The compulsorv proration of oil production has been reviewed by the courts under the legistic conception of the protection of the co-relative rights of in- dividuals within a group as well as under the theory of the proper exercise of the police power to promote the welfare of society as a whole. This is recognition of the principle, adopted b^ the guilds, of restrict 'ng the activities of individ- uals in the interest of the group. Similar measures to restrict the action of individuals to protect the opportunities of a group have come before the courts in situations somewhat analagous, A citv government may establish nones and place restrictions on the construction of buildings; irrigation and reclamation districts have been granted authority to compel individual conformity to the group desire; and in California it is illegal to plant other than one variety of cotton in certain areas. The most drastic acti on to protect the group from the individual we have seen is the recent restriction on the withdrawal of deposits from, banks. It be- came necessary to prorate the amount which each depositor could withdraw from his economic reserve in order to protect the co-relative rights of all depositors. Although the primary motive in proration is to influence prices bv restrict- ing the quantity marketed in the primary channels of trade, this method of influ- encing prices differs from collusion among producers or marketing agencies to name a going or prevailing price. Under proration programs there is a flexibility of prices by reason of the competition of various marketing agencies which market the products . Analyses of the factors affecting the prices of many California crops show that these a re distinct possibilities of increasing the returns to the producers of numerous California crops by limiting shipments in periods of excessive supplies or low consumer purchasing power or both. The possibility of increasing returns by restricting supplies varies, how- ever, from commodity to commodity. The perishability of the product, the size of the market area, the probability of substitutes taking the place of the commodity in question, the probability of production expanding in other areas, and the elasticity of demand are factors which influence it. These factors h-.ve usually been given careful consideration before prorate programs were undertaken. 27. Among the groups of California growers who have undertaken to limit sup- plies in the primary trade channels in periods of excessive supplies are the lemon growers (1925-1932), the Valencia orange growers (1932), the Tokay grape growers (193 2),. the Imperial Valley lettuce and cantaloupe growers (1929-1932), the Wats onvi lie apple growers (1930-31), the canning peach growers (1930-1931), and the raisin, table, and juice grape growers (1930). E r ch of these groups demonstrated that returns to growers could be increased bv such action. Each undertook such action only when it was obvious that returns would be extremely low or severe losses would be incurred in harvesting and marketing if all of the crops were marketed in the primary channels of trade. However, each frroup en- countered the difficulty of obtaining and maintaining participation bv a large proportion of the growers. The principal administrative problem in compulsory prorate programs would be to adjust equitably benefits and burdens among all parties concerned. Other problems would be, (l) determining an industry's desire for such a program, (2) determining the extent to which to prorate on the volume 1o market, and (3) financ- ing and enforcing the program. The method of distributing the burdens and benefits would depend upon sev- eral factors including (1) the possibility of disposing of the quantity which would not be placed in the primary channels of trade at prices which would return har- vesting expenses, (2) in the case of fruits and vegetables, the distribution of the production of and the quantity of first grades, and/or larger sizes, (3) the degree of perishability of the product, and (4) the period of time over which the prorate program would apply. The determination of an industry's desire to conduct a compulsory prorate program might be accomplished by submitting the proposal to qualified growers through election or by petition under the direction of a duly appointed commiss- ion. The extent of proration might be determined by a committee from within the industry. The-' enforcement of prorate programs might be facilitated by the issu- ance of certificates to each producer which stated the Quantity and the time each should, market his proportion of the quantity to be placed in the primary channels of trade. The financing of prorate programs might be accomplished bv collecting fees for such certificates. Under present conditions prorate programs are more desirable from both an individual and social viewpoint than allowing the long-time effect of Itw returns to producers of certain commodities such as tree and vine crops to bring about a reduction in production. One of the principal factors influencing agricultural prices since 1929 has been the low purchasing power of consumers. If sufficient trees and vines were pulled to reduce production to meet the present 1 ow purchas- ing power conditions, plantings would again be stimulated when periods of higher purchasing power prevailed. The ultimate result would be large capital losses. With annual crops the logical procedure is to attempt to adjust acreage to existing demand. Such adjustment may not, however, bring about the necessary ad- justment ifeproduction because the volume of production is influenced by factors other than acreage. For this reason, it is desirable during seasons of excessive supplies to restrict the quantity marketed in the primary channels *f trade. 28. The desirability of makinp participation in prorate programs compulsory in the event a 'large proportion of the producers of a particular commodity desire to engage in them brings to focus the question of the desirability of the exten- sion of governmental control over individual economic activities., U ur view is that if compulsory proration operates to bring about general economic stability fr' increasing present returns to a particular industry, it should be favored. A program in which participation is made compulsory is not an unwarranted restric- tion on individuals' rights since it spreads the benefits and burdens on every grower', in the particular industry. The feasibility of voluntary prorate programs has been clearly establish- ed with some California agriculture industries. Numerous products are produced almost exclusively in this state. It would be impracticable, however, to attempt such programs with many products without the cooperation of the producers in other states. The feasibility of compulsory prorate programs has not been demonstrated in agriculture but has been shown in certain areas in the oil industry. Numerous complex problems would arise in compulsory agricultural proration, yet in our view these are not insurmountable.