UC-NRLF SB 31 131 "<&** REPORT ON THE CHICAGO DOCK PROBLEM With Special Reference to the Questions of Municipal Ownership and Leasing Policy PREPARED FOR JOHN M. EWEN, Chicago Harbor Commissioner BY GEORGE C. SIKES OF (HE UNIVERSITY OF CONTENTS. PAGE. Letter of Transmittal 4 Summary and Conclusions 5 Text of Report I. As to Municipal Ownership of Dock Facilities . 10 II. Leasing Policy 50 III. The Importance to Chicago of the Passenger, Fruit, Vegetable and Package Freight Busi- ness 62 Appendix A Extract from Report of the Street Rail- way Commission to the City Council of Chicago, December, 1900, entitled, "Public Control and Duration of Grants" 68 Appendix B Extracts from the Report of the Metro- politan Improvements Commission, created by act of the Massachusetts Legislature to Study the Boston Situation ,..,..,. , . . , 76 251781; LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL, MR. JOHN M. EWEN, Chicago Harbor Commissioner. Dear Sir : Pursuant to your directions I have prepared and submit here- with a report dealing with certain phases of the Chicago dock problem, especially municipal ownership and leasing policy, to which you suggested that I should give special attention. In preparing the report I have utilized such printed material as was available and have visited in person many of the ports mentioned. For facts relating to the European situation I have drawn chiefly upon the information procured for the Chicago Harbor Commission by Professor Goode. Respectfully submitted, GEORGE C. SIKES. Chicago, October, 1909. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS. In view of the popular controversy that has raged in Chicago over some phases of the municipal ownership question, it is well to draw certain distinctions. Both public sentiment and expert opinion are divided as to the wisdom of public ownership and operaton of such utilities as street railways, lighting plants and telephone systems. With water works systems, however, to take another example, the case is quite different. It is generally con- ceded that plants for furnishing city water should be publicly owned and the tendency is in the direction of the municipaliza- tion of this utility. II. With respect to public ownership, docks properly belong in the same category as water works and not in the class of utili- ties like street railway, lighting and telephone plants that are the subject of controversy in this regard. Experience, the trend of events, and the best official and expert opinion on the subject substantially all lead to the same conclusion that the wisest ultimate policy with regard to what are commonly known as commercial dock facilities, such as it is intended to provide north of the mouth of the Chicago river, is public ownership. Whether the docks shall be constructed and owned by the city from the outset, or whether a private corporation shall be used as the agency for providing them in first instance, under condi- tions that shall admit of their later acquisition by the municipal- ity, is a question of business judgment to be decided according to the concrete situation in any particular case. m. The principal ports of Europe are either publicly owned or are managed by harbor trusts on lines that bear much more sim- ilarity to public than to private ownership. New York has muni- cipal ownership of docks. The ports of New Orleans and San Francisco have public ownership and management by state com- missions. Montreal, the chief port of Canada, has public own- ership and management by a Dominion commission. Boston and Philadelphia have chiefly railroad and private ownership. Bal- timore, with railroad and private ownership, is inaugurating a program of municipal ownership. Galveston presents the most creditable example of development under private ownership to be found in this country, largely because the development, while private, is on the basis of unity. Los Angeles has extended its city limits to the ocean and is planning to make extensive dock developments on the basis of municipal ownership. Oakland, also, has plans for extensive developments on the basis of munic- ipal ownership. Seattle and Tacoma in Washington and Port- land in Oregon have mixed railroad and private ownership. The principal owner of water front property in Vancouver, British Columbia, adapted to shipping purposes, is the Canadian Pacific Railroad. The lake ports usually have a combination of railroad and private ownership. IV. Unity and development according to a comprehensive plan, offering adequate facilities for all applicants on fair terms, are the chief essentials to a well-ordered port. This comprehen- sive plan should take account of rail as well as water terminals. No one with faith in the future water commerce of Chicago can believe that the docks which it is proposed to provide north of the mouth of the Chicago river will prove adequate for future needs. It will be necessary some time to provide additional fa- cilities in some other part of the city. Where, it is difficult to say at this time. The problem calls for further study, separately and in connection with the railway terminal problem and the proposed Lakes-to-the-Gulf waterway. It would seem that the city should make provision for a thorough-going study by ex- perts of Chicago's railroad terminal problem. It would seem also that the General Assembly of Illinois in connection with proposed legislation for the spending of $20,000,000 to promote waterway development, should order an inquiry as to what the connecting channel into Lake Michigan is to be. The present Chicago river cannot be considered satisfactory for that pur- pose. Without proper dock terminals Avith railroad connections and transshipping facilities, open on fair terms to competitive commerce, the Lakes-to-the-Gulf Deep Waterway would fail to accomplish much that is expected of it. V. There is little in the experience of other ports to guide Chi- cago with reference to the proper terms to be incorporated into a franchise grant, in case it should be decided to promote dock development in first instance on the basis of private ownership. More light may be gained on this subject by an examination of Chicago's own experience with other public utilities, especially the street railways, than is to be secured from a study of ports elsewhere. The main features of Chicago's franchise policy as worked out in the traction settlement ordinances are: (1) The reservation to the city of the right to terminate the grant at any time for purchase by the city or by a licensee corporation; (2) the effort to eliminate speculative profits: (3) full publicity of the affairs of the grantee corporation ; (4) controlling participation by the city in the planning and execution of the work of recon- struction. Of these four features the first named is the most vital, although all are important and would seem to be applicable to the dock situation. The problem of proper dock develop- ments in this community presents many difficulties, complexities and uncertainties, and is closely related to other unsolved prob- lems, especially that of proper rearrangement of railroad term- inals. An era of reconstruction and of tremendous improvement is believed to be directly ahead for Chicago. Nothing should be done that cannot be made to fit into whatever larger plan may be worked out. No rights should be created that will stand as a bar to later unity. If the docks under discussion are to be built and owned by a private corporation, it should be only on condi- tion that the owners stand ready to sell at any time to the city or to another licensee corporation, thus making it possible to correlate the docks with other related undertakings, whenever plans for development on a harmonious scale may be worked out. VI. The various arrangements under which boats are permitted to use dock facilities may be divided into three main classifica- tions : First, there is the leasing system, as practiced in New York City, under which boat lines make definite leases of dock space for fixed periods and during the life of the lease have the exclusive control of the particular dock space specified. Then there is the New Orleans system under which the charges are based on the tonnage capacity of the vessel, without regard to the quantity of goods moved over the wharf. New Orleans makes no charge whatever against the goods, but collects its entire revenue from the ship owner. Galveston and Montreal furnish examples of the third system, under which no charge is levied against the vessel, but the entire revenues are raised by a schedule of dues on the commodities moved over the wharf. Some ports have a combination of two or more of these systems. In San Francisco, for example, there is a charge both on vessel and goods. In addition to the three types of charges above men- tioned, there is usually a special charge for the use of sheds, either in the form of sheddage dues or of fixed rental for the use of shed facilities. The storage charges on goods left on the pier longer than specified periods of time is in its nature akin to the storage charge imposed by warehouse concerns. Chicago probably would adopt the pier leasing system, as distinguished from the plan for dockage or wharfage dues, as that system is the simplest and is the one with which the shipping interests of the Great Lakes are most familiar. It should be the policy, how- ever, to have at all times sufficient unleased pier space at which occasional boats may load and unload. For the use of such piers it would be most convenient, perhaps, to provide a sched- ule of wharfage dues, after the manner of Galveston and Mon- treal, imposing a charge of so much a ton on goods moved over the pier. For passenger boats not having regular leased pier space, it would be necessary to devise a system of charges^based probably on the size of the boat. It is of the utmost importance that the principle be adopted that all pier leases or assignments of dock space be subject to revocation on short notice. Possibly at the outset in Chicago it might be expedient to compromise and provide that leases should have ten years of definite duration and after that be subject to revocation at will. Whatever leas- ing policy the city may deem wise for itself it would naturally expect a corporation developing docks under a franchise ar- rangement to follow. If rights of shippers and vesselmen are to be safeguarded under a system of private ownership of docks, provision must be made for continuing public control of dock management, including supervision of all leasing arrangements. VII. The importance to Chicago of the passenger, package freight and fruit and vegetable business has been underestimated here- tofore. The welfare of the city requires that better provision be made for the accommodation of such business. I. AS TO MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF DOCK FACILITIES. In view of the popular controversy that has raged in Chi- cago over some phases of the municipal ownership question, it is well to draw certain distinctions. Both public sentiment and expert opinion are divided as to the wisdom of public ownership and operation of such utilities as street railways, lighting plants and telephone systems. With water-works systems, however, to take another example, the case is quite different. It is generally conceded that plants for furnishing city water should be publicly owned and the tendency is in the direction of the municipalization of this utility. One reason for the public ownership of water plants is that the water supply bears an in- timate relation to the health of a community. Another is that water plants call for large capital outlay, but require a very small operating force as compared with such utilities as street railways and lighting and telephone plants. The city can effect economies by borrowing money at lower rates of interest than can a private corporation, while the management of a water system does not present serious complexities or the patronage dangers inherent in the employment of a large operating force. Of the sixteen water-works plants existing in the United States in 1800, but one was municipally owned. In 1906, nearly 60 per cent, of the water-works plants were municipal property. During the past century 205 plants were changed from private to mun- icipal ownership, while only twenty changed from public to private. Of the thirteen largest cities in the United States, all but one San Francisco own their water-works and San Fran- 11 cisco is clamoring for a change. Of the thirty-eight cities with a population of 100,000 or over in 1900, all but eight own their water plants. With respect to public ownership, docks properly belong in the same category as water-works and not in the class of utili- ties like street railway, lighting and telephone plants that are the subject of controversy in this regard. Docks, to be sure, do not bear the relation to public health that the water system does, but docks do affect in a peculiarly vital manner the com- mercial life of the community. They involve ultimately, if not immediately, large capital outlay, with an operating force smaller even than is required for the management of a water plant. Experience, the trend of events, and the best official and ex- pert opinion on the subject substantially all lead to the same conclusion that the wisest ultimate policy with reference to what are known as commercial dock facilities, such as it is in- tended to provide north of the mouth of the Chicago river, is public ownership. "Whether the docks shall be constructed and owned by the city from the outset, or whether a private cor- poration shall be used as the agency for providing them in first instance, under conditions that shall admit of their later acqui- sition by the municipality, is a question of business judgment to be decided according to the concrete situation presented in any particular case. Types of Ownership. According to types of ownership, docks may be divided into five main classes, as follows : 1. Public ownership, including both state and city owner- ship. 2. The harbor trust. 3. Railroad ownership. 4. Ownership by private corporations or individuals not en- gaged in the transportation business, either rail or water, which permit shipping companies to use the facilities either under a leasing arrangement or on the payment of wharfage. 12 5. Ownership by the boat line which maintains and operates the dock facilities primarily for its own use. The foregoing classification relates to what are characterized as commercial docks. I have not undertaken to deal in-this re- port with industrial harbor facilities, that is, with manufactur- ing locations on navigable waters especially equipped for bring- ing in raw materials of manufacture and taking out finished products by boat. The principal ports of Europe are either publicly owned or are managed by harbor trusts on lines that bear much more similarity to public than to private ownership. The most con- spicuous exception to the prevailing rule in Europe has been London, but even the management of that port has recently been turned over to a harbor trust created by special act of Parliament. Private management of dock facilities in London was found to be productive of high charges and in other ways inconsistent with the most progressive development of the world's metropolis. After a most exhaustive inquiry by a royal commission the change of policy was recommended and Parlia- ment authorized a harbor trust to take over, improve and man- age the dock facilities of London, the price of the properties acquired being about $200,000,000. Professor Goode, in his re- port to the Chicago Harbor Commission (page 105), concludes his account of the transfer of the London dock facilities from private ownership to the harbor trust with this comment : ' "It is most significant for us in Chicago that the best brains in Britain, after years of exhaustive study, have adopted the policy of having one powerful independent monopoly in charge of the business of the port. Pri- vate interests disappear, and the affairs of the port are to be managed as one estate in the interest of all the people doing business in the port; and with the intention not of paying the largest dividend possible, but of giv- ing the best possible service, and paying an interest of only about 3 per cent, on the actual capital investment." The favorite type of port management in Great Britain is that of the harbor trust; in continental Europe direct public ownership is usual. Liverpool, Glasgow and the Tyne ports, in addition to London, have the harbor trust. The Manchester canal project was undertaken by a private corporation actuated 13 by much the same public spirit as a harbor trust. In return for municipal aid in the form of extensive loans, the city was given a majority of the membership of the board of directors, thus making the control dominantly, though indirectly, municipal When the debt is repaid the city's representation on the direc- torate will be reduced. Bristol is a port under municipal man- agement. In Southampton the docks are owned and operated by the London and Southwestern railway. Cardiff offers an instance of private ownership. The Marquis of Bute, owner of extensive coal lands back of Cardiff, found it necessary to develop a harbor as a means of providing facilities for shipping his coal. The port of Havre in France is subject to both na- tional and municipal control. The divided authority, although all public, is the cause of confusion and delay and interferes much with efficiency of management. The Belgian port of Ant- werp is a municipal monopoly, controlled directly by the city council. Rotterdam, Holland's great port, is also under munic- ipal ownership. Hamburg offers a case of state ownership, but the state of Hamburg comprehends little beside the city, so that it is in practical effect municipal ownership. Mixed Ownership in Marseilles. Marseilles, France, is a port with mixed ownership public and private. The beginning of Marseilles as a large seaport dates- from 1856, when a company was given a concession for the development of facilities on the basis of private ownership. A United States consular report of 1895, published in the report on "Docks and Terminal Facilities " by the Massachusetts Com- mission in 1897, gives the following description of the situation in Marseilles at that time : "In 1872, when the business of this port was practically in the hands and under the control of the private company of the docks and entrepots, the commerce had reached such proportions that the docks and wharves were altogether insufficient for the requirements of trade, and reclamations for delay and damage became numerous and frequent, and were generally unheeded. The private company, intrenched in its monopoly, continued to impose its full tariffs, and refused any enlargement of its facilities. To re- lieve this congested and paralyzing condition, new docks were authorized by national legislation in 1874, were begun in 1875 and completed in part 14 in 1881. Public sentiment demanded in strong and vigorous tones the con- struction of new docks, and that they should be owned and controlled by the public authorities as a security and protection for all time against the monopoly and exactions of private companies. Free labor and free~quays was the battlecry of the agitation. Litigation arose; the private com- pany of the docks and entrepots claimed an exclusive concession from the State. The courts decided against the contention of the private company, and the new national docks were undertaken, completed and are now con- trolled by the Marseilles Chamber of Commerce. The competition be- tween the public and private companies has been most beneficial. It has stimulated improvements and multiplied facilities, while the port charges have decreased more than eight per cent, in five years." The report by President Stephens and Chief Engineer Cowie of the Montreal Harbor Commissioners, made in 1908, after a tour of inspection of European ports, found the divided man- agement in Marseilles a barrier to progress. I take the follow- ing from their " General Impressions ' ? of the port of Marseilles: "DIFFERENCES OF OPINION. Lack of harmony between the differ- ent port interests was in evidence, and general dissatisfaction appeared to exist as to the progress of the Port. "AUTHORITIES. The disadvantages were apparent of having three authorities and at least two administrative systems in the Port, viz.: "The Government. ' i The Chambre de Commerce. "The Cie. des Docks et Entrepots. ' ' The visible results of some features of policy with regard to harbour development and administration, may be seen by the transfer of business which formerly was done at Maseille to Genoa, showing that even with Government support and a splendid natural situation, a port may be dis- tanced by foreign competitors." New York's Municipal Dock System. New York, New Orleans and San Francisco, in this country, have publicly owned docks, as has also Montreal, the chief port of Canada. New York's municipal dock system dates from 1870, when the law creating the department of docks of the city was passed by the state legislature. By its early charters New York city had been granted the title to most of the land under water bor- dering upon Manhattan island. Gradually, through transfer of 15 rights to private parties, the city lost control of the greater part of its water front. The wharves in the main were privately owned. There was no orderly development. Facilities were poor and charges high. In the decade prior to 1870, especially, complaint against the inadequacy of facilities was voiced in offi- cial reports and in the press. A private corporation sought the right to take over, under a fifty year lease, what city piers were still left and to acquire and improve others. An organization known as the Citizens' Association supported a bill for the crea- tion of a harbor trust to take charge of the docks of New York and Brooklyn. Neither of these propositions was received with favor. Mayor Hoffman, in a message to the council in 1868, expressed the opinion that the city wharves and piers had never been properly valued. He thought them worth $10,000,000 at that time. He favored putting the docks in charge of a com- mission composed of three members appointed by the mayor and of the sinking fund commissioners. The law enacted two years later embodied a modification of this suggestion. Tweed, who was then in the height of his power, aided the passage of the law and undoubtedly intended to utilize it for purposes of plunder. The exposure came too soon, however, to permit Tweed to profit from manipulation of the dock department. Ac- cording to the provisions of the law, all the expenditures of the dock department, current as well as capital, were to be met out of bond issues which the dock commissioners were to issue, and spend the proceeds thereof, without the -approval or super- vision of the legislative branch of the city government. Even to this day the policy of meeting all expenditures out of bond issues is continued, the receipts in turn all being turned into the sinking fund. The receipts of the dock department since its creation have, as a matter of fact, exceeded its expenditures. The dock department is operating municipal ferries at a loss and using the proceeds of bond issues to pay the deficit. A loss on the municipal ferries was expected, but it is a very difficult matter for the ordinary citizen to learn from the published accounts what the loss is. The method of financing the dock department is unsound and its system of ac- counts and publicity is faulty. The feature of dock department 16 management calling for the most serious criticism, that of leas- ing policy, is considered in the second division of this report. The taking over of the operation of the ferries has added diffi- culties and causes of criticism that would not apply to 4he man- agement of the docks as distinguished from the ferries. The management of the dock department has been criticized from time to come, in official reports and otherwise. Yet nowhere have I seen it seriously suggested that the policy of public ownership of docks in New York was a mistake. On the con- trary, the system of public docks is commonly assigned as one reason for the remarkable commercial development of New York City. With political conditions as they have been in New York for the past forty years, perfection in the dock department was not to be looked for. On the whole, the management of the dock department seems to have been considerably better than might have been expected under the circumstances. On the physical side the development has been especially creditable. Immediately after the organization of the department, an or- derly plan of development was formulated and in the main has been adhered to. Water front rights have been acquired until now the city owns about three-fourths of the water front of Manhattan island. The piers and the sheds, especially the newer ones, are both substantial and elegant in construction. The use of car floats in the harbor of New York is very extensive. The dockage in Brooklyn and on the Jersey shore is mostly under private or railroad ownership. The privately-owned docks of the Hamburg-American and North German Lloyd lines are in Hoboken, on the Jersey side of the river. The ability of these powerful companies to provide themselves with good dock facili- ties does not give them the advantage over weaker companies in the port of New York that they might possess were it not for the dockage accommodations furnished by the city. Since the merging of Brooklyn into Greater New York there has been a movement to bring some of the Brooklyn shore under city ownership. A most interesting private undertaking is that of the Bush Terminal Company in South Brooklyn. This company owns considerable water frontage, projecting from which it has built 17 several extensive piers. In part these piers are utilized by boat lines, but industrial features have been made prominent. Back of the piers are warehouses used for general storage pur- poses. There are also several buildings designed especially for factory purposes. These buidlings are several stories high. Floors or parts of floors are leased to manufacturing concerns. The Bush Terminal Company operates a terminal railroad with tracks connecting the piers, warehouses, and manufacturing buildings. Raw materials or other supplies for the tenants of the manufacturing buildings are landed by boats or car floats at the Bush docks. The Bush Terminal Company makes de- liveries from its receiving docks directly to the floor of the manufacturer by means of its terminal railroad and the elevator service in the building. The finished products of the manufac- turing plants are sent out in the same way. I call attention to this matter as something that may be deserving of study when the time comes for developing further industrial harbor facilities in the Calumet region, along the banks of the Sanitary District canal and on the branches of the Chicago river. New Orleans Under a State Commission. In New Orleans the larger part of the commercial water front of the port is publicly owned and is under the management of a board of commissioners appointed by the governor of the state. The ownership has long been in the city of New Orleans. Fol- lowing some dissatisfaction with city management, a lease of a large portion of the water frontage was made to a private cor- poration in 1891 for a ten-year period. According to the terms of the lease the lessees were authorized to collect and retain for themselves all the charges allowed to be made for the use of the property. This arrangement was productive of still greater dissatisfaction and had not been in operation long before an at- tempt was made to get away from it. The corporation receiving the lease spent little in improvements and took out very large profits. In 1896 a law was passed by the general assembly of Louisiana creating a board of commissioners of the port of New Orleans, the members of which are appointed by the governor. 18 This commission was given power to regulate the commerce and traffic of the harbor, to administer the public wharves, to con- struct new wharves where necessary, and was authorized Jto de- velop the facilities of the port on progressive lines. The board was not able to get control of the public wharves until the ten- year lease made in 1891 had expired. Since the board actually got control, in 1901, extensive improvements have been made. The management of the port appears to have been progressive and capable. Charges have been lowered and there appears to be general satisfaction with the present situation on the part of merchants and vesselmen. The city of New Orleans has brought about the construction of a switching railroad back of the wharves. The railroad is operated by a city commission which works in complete harmony with the port commissioners. The Illinois Central Railroad has an extensive system of dock facilities some little distance north of the center of the city. While these facilities are excellent for the purpose of the Illi- nois Central Railroad, they would not satisfy the needs of the port in general, largely for the reason that they are controlled by a railroad which is interested only in developing its own rail business. The Southern Pacific interests control considerable water frontage across the river from New Orleans, but the tendency of these interests within very recent years has been to make use to a considerable extent of the public docks on the New Or- leans side of the river. This is in marked contrast to the situa- tion in Galveston, where the Southern Pacific has already con- structed its own docks, rather than be dependent upon the facili- ties of the Galveston Wharf Company. The Harbor of San Francisco. The harbor of San Francisco, like that of New Orleans, is managed by a state commission. The policy of state ownership was adopted in 1863. Practically all of the water front avail- able for commercial uses is controlled by the commission. Al- though the harbor management has been subjected to some criti- cism at times, there has been no suggestion of ab^idoning public tt ownership. The present board of harbor commissioners is mak- ing extensive improvements. Some of the IICAV piers now under construction are the best to be found in the country outside of New York City. In one way, the commission has lived from hand to mouth; that is, it has paid for its improvements chiefly out of revenues. This is one of the criticisms made against the port management. Business men say that dock improvements should be paid for out of bond issues and carried out on an extensive scale. This policy is now being adopted. Recent bond issues have made possible the improvements now in progress and it is the expectation to put out other bond issues in the near future as a means of aiding further development. The fact that the management is in the hands of the state rather than the municipality is a cause of some embarrassment in this respect. As the bonds that may be issued by the port of San Francisco are state bonds, authorization for them must be secured by direct act of the legislature and approved by vote of the people of the state at large. It is the theory, of course, that the revenues of the port will be ample to meet both prin- cipal and interest payments, as the port heretofore has been self-sustaining, but the credit of the state is behind the bonds. Los Angeles and Oakland are planning extensive dock improve- ments through the agency of the municipal government, Cali- fornia is a large state with diverse interests and many jealousies. San Francisco is likely to be subject to embarrassment, there- fore, in requesting the state to issue bonds for its port develop- ment. In this respect it is apparent that San Francisco might be better off with municipal management of its docks in place of the present state ownership. Many of the piers in the harbor of San Francisco lack rail- road switch track connections and the port management has been criticised on that account. The Harbor Commissioners within recent years, however, hav6 constructed and now operate a public belt railroad. The newer docks are being provided with switch track facilities and it is the expectation that the de- ficiency of the older docks in this respect will be remedied. The political strength of the teaming interests owners and employes 30 combined evidently has been a factor heretofore in preventing the establishment of railroad switch connections with piers. Oakland, across the bay from San Francisco, is planning ex- tensive harbor developments. Recent litigation has resulted in giving the city title to water front areas that had been occu- pied by private companies. The charter of Oakland has been amended so as to give the city power "to provide for the con- struction, maintenance and use of and on the water front of the city of Oakland, wharves, docks, slips, warehouses, railroads and all other necessary or desirable improvements; to grant fran- chises as now or hereafter provided by law and also for the con- struction and use of wharves, docks, slips, warehouses, railroads and railroad terminals on the water front." It is specifically stipulated that grants to railroads of the privilege to reach the water front shall be without discrimination. It is the announced purpose of the city authorities to undertake extensive develop- ments on the basis of municipal ownership. Montreal's Port a Public Monopoly. The management of the port of Montreal until recently has partaken largely of the character of the English harbor trust. Up to January 1, 1907, the governing body of the port consisted of commissioners appointed by the Dominion government, by the city of Montreal and by various commercial bodies. By the law that became operative January 1, 1907, the board consists of three members, all appointed by the Dominion government, thus making the case one of federal ownership. There was criticism that the larger body, composed of members owing their appoint- ment to divers sources, did not work harmoniously. The Harbor Commissioners control the entire water front of the city and manage it on the basis of a public monopoly. Within the last few years very extensive improvements have been made and more are planned for the near future. The Har- bor Commissioners own and operate a belt railroad, the tracks of which are located on the property they control so that switch engines may be operated at any time of the day or night. In some places, notably Boston, Philadelphia and Baltimore, the 21 switching of cars, in parts of the harbor at least, is prohibited except at night. The facilities for the interchange of com- modities between the railroad and the boat line are especially good in Montreal. The Harbor Commissioners own grain ele- vators which recently have been equipped with conveyor sys- tems that make it possible for the boat to take on grain at the berth to which it goes to unload its cargo. The Harbor Com- missioners own the portions of the water front devoted to in- dustrial uses, as well as those on which commercial docks are maintained. For industrial purposes the commission makes leases to plants, running for varying periods, but usually for not more than forty years. The port of Montreal is closed by ice nearly half of each year and is subject to other disadvantages. The improvements are not as expensive as in cities having a larger volume of traffic. But in adaptation to its needs, the dock system of Montreal is one of the best on the continent. It is so, largely because the development is on a basis of unity, the harbor commissioners being the sole owners of dock facilities in the port. The presi- dent of the board, Mr. George W. Stephens, and the chief engi- neer, Mr. Frederick "W. Cowie, recently made a report, based on a tour of personal inspection, on "British and Continental Ports with a View to the Development of the Port of Montreal and Canadian Transportation." In that report they give the follow- ing as one of the features of success of any port : "(b) Ownership and Control of the Entire Harbor Area. No com- plete development can take place without unity of purpose and concentra- tion of authority. The value of complete. ownership and the non-alienation of any territory or rights are inestimable. The existence of rights, fran- chises or privileges in the hands of individuals may hamper business and endanger or discourage further extension. " The following are some of the "General Impressions" of Mr. Stephens and Mr. Cowie, as set forth in their report : "1. The ports that are doing the biggest business, and doing it most efficiently, are the ports that have kept their facilities ahead of actual re- quirements. "2. The ports that ha,ve remained stationary or lost in. prestige have been those that neglected to provide facilities before business was forced to seek elsewhere the same facilities provided by rival terminals. Business follows the facilities. ' ' 3. Unity of authority, concentration of business, depthr of water areas, and facilities for despatch of business are the prominent character- istics of successful port administration. "4. The necessity of providing large and convenient storage areas where cargo may be collected and cared for. "5. The lowest cost of handling cargo from the hold of the ship to consignee and vice versa, was found to be in a port where one authority controlled the entire operation, and where the transit sheds were three to five stories high. ' ' Having dealt with the four ports on the American continent in which the ownership is entirely, or chiefly, public, I will now proceed to consider ports having a mixture of public, private, and railroad ownership. The Lesson of the Boston Situation. Boston, to my mind, is instructive chiefly for the lesson in its failure to grasp the needs of its situation and to move aggressive- ly for their satisfaction. The backwardness of Boston with re- spect to dock facilities is in marked contrast with its progressive activities in some other municipal lines. Boston has had more re- ports and studies made of its dock situation and has done less to improve conditions than most other communities. An examina- tion of some of these various official reports may prove instruct- i\e. In 1895, the legislature of Massachusetts created a commis- sion to conduct "an investigation of the wants of the port of Bos- ton for an improved system of docks and wharves, and terminal facilities in connection therewith." The commission was spe- cifically instructed to make a general study of the question of public ownership of docks and wharves and the desirability of the adoption of public ownership in Boston. The report prepared contained much information and was able and instructive. It found in favor of the general policy of public ownership. The following quotation indicates the point of view: ' ' Wharves are the means whereby the public on land can transfer them- selves and their goods to the water, and vice versa, just as turnpikes, streets and highways are the means for enabling free and easy transporta- tion wholly on land. No impediments or barriers beyond the limit of pub- lic control should be permitted to obstruct freedom of communication be- tween land and water. The rivers and seas are the highways of water- borne freight and passengers, and the right of landing and embarking ought to suffer no more or greater legal obstruction than the right of traversing the highway on sea or land. It becomes the duty of the public, then, to preserve that right for present and future use. "In order to reap the fullest enjoyment of this right, facilities and conveniences must be supplied for the required use. These necessarily be- come a charge, owing to the cost of construction and maintenance, in con- sequence of which a toll must be paid by the users. This toll is an una- voidable obstruction to free transference over a wharf which is built for increased accommodation and for lessening the cost of handling. But it is obvious that the smaller the toll the less will be the obstruction. "Aside, however, from questions of natural right and justice, there are other business and practical considerations which appear as satisfactory reasons, as given in the communication of our consuls from different ports. ***** "In addition to the foregoing, from the testimony which this commis- sion has been able to gather, both through the agency of its committee who went abroad in the summer of 1895, when they conferred with the leading merchants and officials of seventeen foreign ports (and elsewhere), and from correspondence and personal interviews, held with the representa- tives of various ports in this country, this commission has become satisfied that the reasons for public ownership and control reside, as hereinbefore stated, not only in those natural rights which underlie the exercise of true popular liberty, but in that business sagacity and far-sighted prudence which is able to apply the principles of economy, to realize that delay means cost and despatch means profit, and that uniform and stable charges attract as fixed factors in a business calculation, and also in the under- standing that all these elements are most completely suppled through pub- lic ownership and control.'' While this commission found in favor of the general prin- ciple of public ownership of docks, and recommended certain developments by the state in the harbor of Boston, it failed to apprehend a principle of dock policy of more importance even than that of public ownership. The following is the opening paragraph of its summary of conclusions and recommendations: "Public Ownership of Foreshore. That a portion of the foreshore should forever be preserved in the ownership and control of the people, for uses and purposes such as the needs of changing conditions may from 24 time to time require, but that it is neither necessary nor desirable that the entire foreshore of the harbor should be thus heldj on the contrary, a diversified ownership is believed to be healthiest, and therefore the ac- quisition of certain parcels within the limits of the city of Boston, as here- inbefore described, is recommended. " In finding for "diversified ownership" of port facilities, the Massachusetts commission ran counter to the teachings of ex- perience and the recommendations of practically all other offi- cial and expert reports upon the subject. Unity of management and development according to a comprehensive plan are the first requisites to the highest type of port. The curse of the Boston situation is unrelated diverse ownership. On the strength of the recommendation made by this com- mission, a pier was built in the Commonwealth Flats of South Boston, known as Commonwealth pier. It was completed in 1901, at a cost of $381,877.09. The pier is 1,200 feet long and 400 feet wide. It is not equipped with sheds and is without switch track connections. Not even a regular street has been opened to give connection with the pier, although it is possible to drive from the street to the pier over unoccupied land. Un- der the circumstances it is small wonder that the pier has been little used and that the revenue derived from it since its con- struction had amounted in 1908 to onty $12,847.19. Failure to lay switch tracks to the Commonwealth pier presumably is due to the hostility of railroad interests. The failure to open a street to the pier has been due to the inability to secure the co-opera- tion of governmental agencies having control of such matters. The legislature of Massachusetts in 1907 again ordered an in- quiry, this time by the Board of Harbor and Land Commission- ers, into "the cost and advisability of constructing and main- taining a system of metropolitan docks in the city of Boston to be owned and controlled either by the Commonwealth or by the said city." This board, still accepting as gospel the finding of the prior commission, that diverse ownership of harbor facilities was de- sirable, reached the following conclusion: "For various reasons briefly indicated above, the Board does not think 25 it advisable at present to construct and maintain a system of metropolitan docks in Boston. The time may come when such construction would seem advisable, but at present it is in the opinion of the Board premature." In leading up to this conclusion, the board had the following to say: "The advisability of constructing and maintaining a system of piers under public control would seem to depend primarily on the immediate ne- cessity for more dock accommodations, and the improbability of the work being undertaken under private ownership. "At the public hearing on the resolve no sentiment or opinion was expressed in favor of public ownership of docks. The answers of various persons to written inquiries by the Board did not favor public ownership and control of wharves and docks; on the contrary, many persons ex- pressed themselves in opposition. Even the most advanced advocates of public ownership do not advocate public ownership and control in advance of some general demand or necessity in some particular line or business. * # * * * ' ' The Commonwealth pier might be equipped with sheds, warehouses, railroad tracks and hoists, if only some one could indicate the use to which the pier would be put. Sheds sufficient for cheap bulk freight would not answer for storage of valuable cargo. Various things are left in doubt until a use is indicated or a tenant discovered. Besides these practical questions there is the public question of going into the dock and wharfage business in competition with private owners. There are other available docks ready for use at the market rates, and persons ready to build more docks on demand. If the Commonwealth is to enter the dock, wharfage and warehouse business, it would seem proper for the Legislature to first con- sider and decide the question. " Of all the official reports which I have seen dealing with the subject of docks, this is the only one to pass even mild disap- proval upon the policy of public ownership, and this entire re- port it seems to me is detrimental in its influence upon the proper development of Boston, not so much because it fails to approve of public ownership as because it fails to comprehend the pressing need of Boston with reference to dock facilities and management. The report of the president and chief engineer of the Harbor Commissioners of Montreal reflected the experi- ence of all the progressive ports of the world and the judgment of practically all the official and expert opinion on the subject outside of Boston when it said: "No complete development can take place without unity of purpose and concentration of authority. ' ' The Prime Need of Boston. The Boston and Maine and the Boston and Albany railroads have very good dock facilities in Boston, but in each case the docks are maintained and operated as accessories of the rail- roads that own them. These separate sets of docks are not correlated with each other or with the remaining dock facili- ties of the city, nor do they meet the needs of Boston as a busi- ness community for dock facilities. The New York, New Haven and Hartford railroad also owns several piers that must be con- sidered good merely as piers that form the water terminal of a railroad system, although for some reason they are very little used. The Commonwealth's new pier, located just beyond the New York, New Haven and Hartford piers, although seemingly offering a good example of mere pier construction, is also little used, as already pointed out. The dockage facilities on the main peninsula of Boston which are used for the accommoda- tion of vessels engaged in the coastwise and excursion business are a veritable hodgepodge. The ownership is diverse. The development is scraggly and uneven. Much of the property is used for purposes that do not call for water front locations. The rentals charged are high and new lines seeking dock facilities would have difficulty in finding accommodations in this part of the harbor, which is where they need to be. Only a few of the piers have switch tracks. The belt railroad located behind the piers is situated in a busy public street and can be utilized only at night. The prime need of Boston, it would appear, is to have this portion of its water front taken over and improved on a basis of unity by some single authority. To be sure it would cost a large amount of money to acquire this property, but its revenue-producing possibilities would be increased by rearrange- ment and improvement by a single authority according to some orderly plan. The welfare of the community as a whole would be promoted by such a course. There is very general agreement that the dockage facilities of Boston ar- unsatisfactory and unsuited to the Bleeds of com- 27 merce. Mr. Desmond Fitzgerald, the engineer, expressed the sentiment on that question which one hears generally from the men who understand the situation in Boston, when he said in his report to the Metropolitan Improvements Commission: "No one versed in sane construction can visit the dock terminals of Boston without realizing that they are in the main the product of haphazard and patchwork policy largely unworthy of the port and unsafe for present and expected passenger and freight business." The Metropolitan Improvements Commission, created by the legislature of Massachusetts in 1907 to study the Boston situa- tion, to my mind manifested a much keener appreciation of the nature of the problem, confronting Boston than either of the two reports thus far considered. The extracts from the report of this commission which I de- sire to present are too extended for insertion in the text of this report. Hence, they are published at the end as "Appendix B." The burden of the report is that development should be under- taken in accordance with a comprehensive plan, and that that plan should take account not only of water terminals, but of rail terminals as well. While the suggestion of the Metropolitan Improvements Com- mission is that the work of improvement be undertaken by a terminal company, it lays due emphasis upon the need for public direction in such matters. It is recommended that the Common- wealth be given a direct hand in the management of the terminal company through the election by it of a definite proportion of the board of directors. The report of the Metropolitan Improvements Commission has only recently been made public. Presumably its recom- mendations will receive the serious attention of the legislature that meets next winter. The Move for Municipal Ownership in Philadelphia and Baltimore. Philadelphia is a port which has suffered much from railroad domination. The Pennsylvania and the Philadelphia and Eead- 38 ing railroad companies own a large proportion of the water front. The city owns a few piers, while others are the property of various private owners. There is a strong public sentiment for the municipal ownership of more docks, as evidenced by the action of business organizations, led by the Maritime Exchange, in securing legislation enlarging the city's charter powers. In response to this movement the legislature in 1907 enacted a law creating a department of wharves, docks and ferries and au- thorizing the city to acquire, construct and own additional piers. There has been considerable adverse public criticism because the first head of the Department of Wharves, Docks and Ferries made no serious move to carry out the purpose of the act with reference to the acquisition by the city of additional dockage facilities. There has recently been a change in the head of this department and it is expected that more active steps will be taken in the near future in furtherance of the purpose of the act creating the department. No well-defined comprehensive program of dock development appears to have been worked out in Philadelphia. The idea seems to be merely that the dock de- partment shall create new piers wherever there are available lo- cations. However, the situation in Philadelphia is naturally simpler than that in Boston and in some other cities. In Baltimore, as in Philadelphia, the principal dockage facili- ties have been owned by the railroads, together with diverse private ownership. The movement for municipal ownership of docks, which is now Avell under way in Baltimore, received its chief impetus from the great fire of 1904. In accordance with the recommendations of the Burnt District Commission, the Har- bor Board was created as a sub-department of the Department of Public Improvements. The legislature conferred upon the city the power to acquire the title to water front property and construct piers thereon. Inasmuch as the docks in the business center had been destroyed by fire, it was a natural thing for the city to begin the work of pier construction in that area. New harbor lines were established and a plan of comprehensive de- velopment outlined to be carried out as rapidly as the condi- tions should warrant. The small and inadequate piers were re- placed by larger ones having slips of greater width and other- 29 Avise better fitted for the accommodation of shipping. Balti- more, on account of the fire, is doing what Boston should do, that is, beginning the work of reconstruction in the very center of the harbor where property values are the highest. Norfolk has a combination of railroad and private ownership with some street ends still in the possession of the city. New- port News is an example of a railroad-owned port, the dockage facilities there being the property of the Chesapeake and Ohio railroad. v The Galveston Wharf Company. The port of Galveston presents the best example of private ownership coming within my observation. This is because the development in Galveston, although private, is upon the basis of unity. The Galveston Wharf Company was incorporated by spe- cial act of the Texas legislature, in 1854, the original name be- ing the Galveston Wharf and Cotton Press Company. The com- pany owned the land bordering on the water, but the city owned the street ends. After considerable controversy between the company and the city a compromise arrangement was arrived at in 1869, under which the city gave the street ends to the com- pany in return for which the company turned over to the city one-third of its capital stock. By the arrangement the city names one-third of the directorate, but is not allowed to vote its stock in the selection of the other directors. In order to in- sure control of the affairs of the company by the private stock- holders, it is expressly stipulated that in all stockholders' meet- ings no measure shall be adopted or action taken except by the vote of three-fourths of all the stock of the company, exclusive of that held by the city. While, therefore, the city has one- third of the stock and thus receives one-third of the dividends declared, and while it is represented on the board of directors, the dominating control in shaping the policy of the company is private. The Galveston Wharf Company is' a wharf company pure and simple. It is not interested in transportation lines, either rail or water, except that it owns and operates the belt railroad which gives switch track connections with the piers. The facili- 30 ties offered for the accommodation of shipping are creditable. The only criticism offered is that the charges are said by some to be high. The Southern Pacific railroad has already -estab- lished dock facilities of its own in the port of Galveston and it is said that the Rock Island and Santa Fe systems will do the same in the near future, as a means of economy. This action of the three railroads creates diversity where before there was unity, but this does not signify so much in Galveston as it might in other situations. The Galveston Wharf Company controls the water front nearest to the business center of the city and will continue to develop and manage that according to a har- monious plan. The three railroad systems in question probably will not undertake to do more than provide landing places for vessels doing an extensive business with the particular railroad. The Galveston Wharf Company has not paid large dividends, but it is supposed to be putting a considerable proportion of its earnings into permanent improvements. The great storm of 1900 put the company to an expense of about $650,000 in repairing damage done to its property. There appears to be no demand for public ownership and management of the wharf system in Galveston. On account of its misfortunes the city has been put to heavy expense in mak- ing public improvements and is evidently satisfied to leave to the Galveston Wharf Company the task of keeping the wharves in condition for the accommodation of shipping. Although the volume of shipping through the port of Galves- ton is large, the city itself is small, and the local business conse- quently is of less importance. Galveston is primarily a transfer point between the boats and the railroads. There is not, there- fore, so much need for public ownership in Galveston from the community point of view as might be the case in a larger city in which the local business was a matter of more concern. Rail- roads are the chief parties in interest in the Galveston situa- tion, inasmuch as their rates on traffic through the port of Gal- veston must take account of the wharf charges at that port and the railroads are better able to look out for themselves than would be a large number of smaller shippers not so closely 31 bound together. Some of the railroads, as already stated, are looking out for themselves by building docks of their own. Activity in Los Angeles. Los Angeles is a city that has been aroused to the need for progressive port development largely by the hope that the open- ing of the Panama canal will mean a tremendous increase in the volume of shipping for the Pacific coast. Los Angeles is situ- ated some twenty-five miles from the Pacific ocean. Its natural port is the harbor of San Pedro, adjacent to which are the vil- lages of San Pedro and Wilmington. These villages, of course, were unable to develop the port facilities on a public basis and private interests seemed destined to get control of all the avail- able water frontage. To forestall this, Los Angeles outlined and carried through a plan for consolidation with the villages of San Pedro and Wilmington which should enable it to take charge of the development of the harbor of San Pedro. With considerable difficulty an enabling act was secured from the legislature designed to permit Los Angeles to take in a narrow strip of land running from the original limits of the city to the seacoast, and then spreading out to take in the villages of San Pedro and Wilmington. Strong efforts were made by private interests to defeat the project through an adverse vote in one or the other of the villages. In order to carry the proposition through, the leaders of the consolidated movement in Los An- geles give assurance that $10,000.000 would be spent by the city of Los Angeles in the next ten years in the development of mun- icipal docks in the harbor of San Pedro. The vote for the con- solidation in San Pedro was 726 for to 227 against. The vote in Wilmington was 107 for to 61 against consolidation. The strength of the movement in Los Angeles proper was indicated by the fact that the vote there for the proposition was in excess of 13,000 to only about 200 against. These votes were taken in August last. Litigation has al- ready been started with a view to recovering for the public water frontage areas which it is contended are now held illegally by private parties. A view of the map of the consolidated area gives one the impression that Los Angeles is literally reaching out its arm to the ocean to seize its share of the future shipping of the Pacific coast. Seattle's Wise Plans Thwarted. Seattle, Washington, with an excellent location on Puget Sound, is an example of a community which started out, upon the admission of the state of Washington into the Union in 1889, with the deliberate intention of having public ownership, but which finds itself thwarted in that respect. Following are some of the provisions of the constitution of Washington, adopted at the time of the admission of the state to the Union: Article XV, Section I. The Legislature shall provide for the appoint- ment of a commission whose duty it shall be to locate and establish harbor lines in the navigable waters of all harbors, estuaries, bays and inlets of this state, wherever such navigable waters lie within or in front of the cor- porate limits of any city or within one mile thereof upon either side. The state shall never give, sell, or lease to any private person, corporation, or association any rights whatever in the waters beyond such harbor lines, nor shall any of the area lying between any harbor line and the line of ordi- nary high tide, and within not less than fifty feet nor more than 600 feet of such harbor line (as the commissioners shall determine) be sold or granted by the state, nor its right to control the same relinquished, but such area shall be forever reserved for landings, wharves, streets, and other conven- iences of navigation and commerce. Article XV, Section 2. The Legislature shall provide general laws for the leasing of the right to build and maintain wharves, docks, and other structures upon the areas mentioned in Section 1 of this article, but no lease shall be made for any term longer than thirty years, or the Legislature may provide by general laws for the building and maintaining upon such area, wharves, docks, and other structures. Article XVII, Section 1. The State of Washington asserts its owner- ship to the beds and shores of all navigable waters in the state up to and including the line of ordinary high tide, in waters where the tide ebbs and flows, and up to and including the line of ordinary high water within the banks of all navigable rivers and lakes: Provided, That this section shall not be construed so as to debar any person from asserting his claim to vested rights in the courts of the state. Article XXVII, Section 2. All laws now in force in the territory of Washington, which are not repugnant to this constitution, shall remain in force until they expire by their own limitation, or are altered or re- pealed by the Legislature: Provided, That this section shall not be so con- 33 strued as to validate any act of the Legislature of Washington Territory granting shore or tide lands to any person, company, or any municipal or private corporation. It was the evident intent of the framers of the Washington constitution that the state should maintain the ownership of the water front of the cities of the state in much the same man- ner as California had retained the ownership of the water front of S'an Francisco. This intent was even recognized by the Su- preme Court of the United States in an opinion rendered Decem- ber 19, 1892, delivered by Chief Justice Fuller, in the case of "Yesler vs. The Harbor Line Commission," in which it was said: "The design of the state law is to prohibit the encroachment by private individuals and corporations on navigable waters, and to secure a uniform water front." The first Harbor Line Commission that was appointed took this view both of the constitution and of the act of the legisla- ture creating it. In its second and final report, submitted in 1893, this commission, after quoting portions of the opinion of the Supreme Court of the United States in the Illinois Central Lake Front case, proceeded to say: "For these and other reasons mentioned in the exhaustive opinion of the court, delivered by Mr. Justice Field, it was held that the grant made by the Legislature was a revocable one, and that no legislature had the right to make a permanent transfer of the public property of the people of the State of Illinois in their navigable waters to any private corporation. It is precisely in accordance with the principles laid down in the decision from which we have just quoted, that the people of the State of Washington have wisely determined to reserve from sale and reserve for public use so much of the water front in its harbors, not exceeding six hundred feet in width, as may be necessary for commercial purposes. In view of the fact that the navigable waters of the state and the lands under them should be held for public use, and also of the further fact that the jurisdiction of the United States extends over these navigable waters, the State of Wash- ington has very wisely and properly refrained from any attempt to sell or dispose of any tide lands below the line of mean low water. The State of Illinois and other states of the Union, notably New Jersey, have gotten themselves into serious difficulties not only with their own citizens, but with the National Government, by undertaking to sell, grant and otherwise dispose of, in fee simple, the lands they own under their navigable waters. The tide lands of the State of Washington, which lie between high and low. 34 water, may be sold without injury to the interests of commerce arid naviga- tion, but we think a mistake would be made if any measures were adopted looking to the disposal of the lands below the line of low waler._ These lands should be kept for public use, together with all areas reserved within established harbor lines and water ways. The history of those older states which have large commercial interests is full of the evidence of loose, negli- gent or wilfully corrupt management of their properties upon the water front of their various harbors. The state and city of New York, for ex- ample, have been striving for years in the courts, by means of condemna- tion proceedings and otherwise, at vast expense, to recover their control of the water front of that city, in order that it may be properly main- tained and improved for the public benefit. In the year 1810, the city granted to John Jacob Astor certain water lots in the lower part of the city of New York, aggregating 425 feet and 4 1-4 inches along the water front at a yearly rental of $356.91. In the year 1892, his heirs were paid, after a long and expensive course of litigation, the sum of $520,709.49, in order to secure their relinquishment of the claim they held to wharfage rights upon this property. Other examples of a similar character might be quoted. It is certainly desirable that the State of Washington should avoid as far as possible the errors and mistakes of management into which the older states have fallen in the care of so valuable and important a public trust." A Great Opportunity Wasted. When this Harbor Line Commission undertook to lay out harbor lines in furtherance of its announced policy it was bit- terly opposed by various interests. Through litigation this com- mission was estopped from carrying out its program and laying out harbor lines in accordance therewith in Seattle and in other principal cities of the state. The expiration of the term of office of the commission found its work uncompleted. The legislature made provision for a new harbor line commission differently constituted. This new commission proceeded to lay out harbor lines in Seattle and the other large cities which clearly did vio- lence to the spirit of the constitution. The inner harbor line was located well out in deep water, in many cases several hun- dred feet beyond the actual physical inner harbor line. The outer harbor line, of course, would be still farther out. In many cases the inner harbor line, as located by the new commission, was beyond the end of the piers as actually constructed, and in the case of the longer piers even as now T existing, not more than 35 300 or 400 feet of the piers extends beyond the inner harbor line. The land under water inside the inner harbor line as constituted by the new commission was then sold at nominal prices to the owners of the adjacent shore lands. Thus the piers of moderate length became private property. The longer piers were partially private property and partially on land belonging to the state, the portion of the land under water on which the pier rested outside the inner harbor line being leased by the state to the pier owner for a thirty-year period at a nominal rental. Thus Seattle, despite its constitutional provisions designed to insure state ownership and uniform development, in reality has private ownership and scraggly and uneven development. The land un- der water to which the state has retained title under the harbor lines as laid out is of little value for dockage purposes. The city of Seattle is the owner of a number of street ends, but these street ends, as a rule, merely serve as slips for the benefit of the privately owned piers on either side thereof. There are citizens of Seattle who contend that the situation as actually developed is a fraud upon its face and a perversion of the letter as well as the spirit of the constitution of the state. It is likely that this contention will some day be pushed to the point where the courts will be obliged to pass upon it. One cannot look into the situation in Seattle without feeling that a great opportunity has been wasted by that city. Dock property now privately owned, but which was intended to re- main the property of the state, has increased enormously in value in recent years. Had title remained in the state, the pub- lic would have been in a position to derive large revenue from the leases of dock facilities, or it would have been in a position to provide for a reduction in charges for the benefit of commerce. The ownership is railroad and private. The situation re- minds one much of that in Boston, the development in both places being scraggly and uneven and much of the water front property is devoted to business purposes other than the accom- modation of shipping. Seattle is much better off than Boston, however, in that it has good switch track facilities connected with the railroads operating in Eailroad avenue back of the piers, 36 The original law provided that 75 per cent, of the revenues derived from the sale of tide lands in any given port should be used as a special fund "for the construction and maintenance of a system of permanent and substantial improvements in aid of commerce and navigation in and for the harbor of such city or town wherein such tide lands may be sold." It was evidently the intention that the state should embark upon a policy of construction and ownership of dock facilities as was done in San Francisco. But the revenues derived from the sale of tide lands have not been utilized for this purpose. A vital defect of the situation in Seattle is that there is no harbor authority as such, of any importance. There is a harbor master in Seattle, but his powers and duties are very limited. The state's agent in looking after wharf property is the com- missioner of public lands, who, as the name of the office implies, concerns himself chiefly with the state's interest as a land owner. There is no official charged with the duty of looking after the public's interests in the harbors of the state from the naviga- tion or commercial point of view. The situation in Tacoma is very much the same as that in Seattle. Control of practically all the water front has passed into the hands of the railroads and other private owners. There is some agitation in Seattle to create a port authority to look after tne shipping interests of the city. A bill urged for passage in the last legislature, but without success, gave to the particular commission it was intended to create, power to take property, construct docks, and to raise part of the revenue therefor by special assessment upon property benefited. It was specially made the duty of this commission to "adopt a compre- hensive scheme of harbor development. " Portland, Oregon, located on the Willamette river, has di- verse ownership, partially railroad and partially private. As in other such ports, the developments are scraggly and uneven, with a water front devoted to a considerable extent to business purposes other than the accommodation of shipping. There ap- pears to be some agitation on the part of the public for munic- ipal ownership of docks in Portland, although there is no official 37 movement in that direction. A recent public policy referendum vote showed a substantial majority in favor of public ownership. Vancouver, British Columbia, furnishes a case of railroad ownership, nearly all the water front devoted to dockage uses being the property of the Canadian Pacific railroad. The piers devoted to the general shipping business are operated by com- panies that take leases from the Canadian Pacific railroad. The principal purpose of the development that has thus far taken place is to serve the interests of the Canadian Pacific railroad as a rail carrier. The local interests of the port have been treated as secondary. In the Great Lakes Ports. In the ports of the Great Lakes rail and private ownership is the rule. In some of these ports exceptional facilities have been provided for handling the great bulk commodities of lake com- merce. The facilities of Duluth, for example, for sending out iron ore and receiving coal, are remarkably good. Cleveland, like- wise, has an especially good equipment for loading coal onto the vessels. The accommodations for the passenger and package freight boats are commonly owned either by railroad companies or by the boat lines themselves. There is very little public own- ership of docks on the Great Lakes nor is there ownership by companies engaged in the dock business, like the Galveston Wharf Company. Practically all the water front of Buffalo is owned by the various railroads which also control the boat lines engaged in the package freight business at that port. As was pointed out in the report submitted by me to the Harbor Com- mission, this railroad control of dock facilities in Buffalo does much to enable the railroads to dominate the lake shipping busi- ness and to keep independent boat lines out of the field, to the detriment of the entire area naturally tributary to the Great Lakes. The principal dockage facilities in Milwaukee are owned by the Chicago, Milwaukee and St. Paul railroad. The facili- ties afforded by these docks for handling package freight through Milwaukee are much more satisfactory than the facili- ties offered in Chicago and help to explain the rapid growth of the package freight traffic in the port of Milwaukee. The fol- 38 lowing table shows the combined receipts and shipments by tons of unclassified freight of the ports of Chicago (including South Chicago) and Milwaukee, for the years named: Chicago. Milwaukee. 1901 1,465,339 923,423 1902 1,899,418 1,064,172 1903 1,645,084 983,694 1904 1,432,608 953,095 1905 1,738,096 1,116,121 1906 1,640,010 1,162,950 1907 1,733,678 1,545,920 Chicago is in the crudest stage, in which each boat line is expected to look out for itself and find dockage accommodations where it can. The various railroad companies have piers where vessels can take on and unload freight for that particular rail- road. But for its city and miscellaneous business each boat company must have accommodations of its own. It would be .more economical and better for all concerned if a system of piers could be provided where all the boats engaged in the pas- senger business and in the package freight and fruit and vege- table traffic could be brought together. The comparison of charges of different ports is a matter of very great difficulty because of the different systems in use. With New Orleans collecting its revenues by dockage dues against the vessel and Galveston imposing charges only against the goods, it is not an easy matter to decide which port gives the cheaper service and how much the difference may be. The difficulty is increased many fold in undertaking to compare either New Orleans or Galveston with New York City, where most of 'the piers are under rental and no such charges as dockage or wharfage appear. The Royal Commission appointed to inquire into the adminis- tration of the port, of London made very elaborate comparisons of the charges of London with other ports and found the charges in London to be higher than in cities with public ownership or harbor trust management. A statement prepared on January 3, 1907, for the Commis- 39 sioners of the Port of New Orleans gives the actual charges paid by the Civilian of the Harrison line in the port of New Orleans as $894.06. The statement as submitted to the New Orleans commissioners purports to figure what the charges would have been on the same vessel and its cargo in the port of Galveston, on the basis of the Galveston wharfage rates. According to this statement, the charges against the vessel and cargo in the port of Galveston would have been $4,201.53, or more than four times the actual charges in the port of New Orleans. Although there can be no doubt that the charges for service in New Orleans under public ownership are lower than in Galveston under pri- vate ownership, it is improbable that the average disparity would be as much as this particular statement shows. There can be no doubt, either, that the dock charges in San Francisco under public ownership are lower than in Seattle and other ports on the Pacific Coast under private ownership, al- though it is difficult to deal in precise figures. In Seattle the prevailing charge is 50" cents a ton Tjpon goods moved over the wharf, with no charge against the vessel. The prevailing charge against goods in San Francisco is only 5 cents a ton, but there is also a dockage charge against the vessel. The officials in San Francisco claim that their dockage charge against the vessel, 'combinJed with the toll of 5 cents a ton against the goods, amounts to about one-third or one-half of the charge imposed against the goods in Seattle. Montreal, at the eastern terminus of the Canadian Pacific Railroad, under public ownership, has much lower schedules of dock charges than Vancouver, the Pacific terminal of the Canadian Pacific Railway, under railroad ownership. As before stated, however, no charge whatever is made in the railroad-' owned port on goods having a rail haul. The charges of Montreal are comparable with the charges of Galveston, or with those of the railroad-owned docks in Boston upon goods not having a rail haul. The Montreal rates are much lower. The dock charge on asphalt, for example, in the port of Montreal is 8 cents per ton. In Galveston it is l 1 ^ cents per 100 pounds, or 25 cents a ton, while in Boston the charge 40 is 40 cents for a long ton of 2,240 pounds. Other items are likely to show about the same differences. The Benefits of Public Ownership. A study of the principal ports of the world discloses that those with the most progressive development are owned by pub- lic authorities, either state or municipal, or are managed by harbor trusts. The chief exception is Galveston, which fur- nishes an example of progressive development under private control. Railroad ownership of docks affords efficient service, as a rule, for railroad purposes, but railroad-owned docks do not satisfy the needs of a community for facilities for handling traffic not transferred to or from railroad carriers. "Where one raiload owns the docks, other railroads are placed at a disad- vantage, to the injury of the community at large. Moreover, while railroads encourage connecting ocean traffic, with which rail competition is impossible, they seek to suppress coastwise traffic and inland water transportation. Control of dock facili- ties is an important aid to the railroads in suppressing competi- tion by water carriers. As a rule the most wide awake and public spirited communities that have private ownership of docks are making moves to bring about public ownership. Unity and development according to a comprehensive plan are the chief essentials to a well ordered port. It is rare in- deed that private ownership signifies harmonious development on a basis of unity. And where it does there is the specter of man- agement in the interest of private monopoly. Diverse private ownership means scraggly, uneven and unrelated development. Boston, Seattle and Portland afford good illustrations of this point. A mixture of public and private ownership may, of course, give the same result. But a usual purpose of public ownership or harbor trust management is to promote unity. Therefore, partial public ownership is likely to lead ultimately to complete public ownership. Practically all the official and expert declarations on the subject are in favor of public or harbor trust management of docks. The only exception within my knowledge is the report 41 made in 1907 by the Massachusetts Harbor and Land Commis- sioners, to which reference has already been made. The harbor trust idea has not been taken up in this country. Under the harbor trust plan the management of a port is en- trusted to a group of men constituting a legal entity, chosen in various ways. Usually a part of the number is chosen by desig- nated governmental authorities and the rest elected by the ship- ping interests of the port. The trust authority borrows money on the revenues of the port and in other ways manages its af- fairs like a private corporation. But there are no profits either to stockholders or to members of the board who direct its af- fairs. After interest allowance, and the payment of expenses, the surplus revenues are devoted to improvements or charges are lowered. The aim is merely to make the port management self-sustaining. It will be seen that the harbor trust plan is really more akin in nature to public ownership than to private ownership. The Harbor Trust Idea. The savings banks of the New England states and of New York are managed on somewhat the same plan, except that the trustees of the savings banks, instead of being appointed or elected as are the members of the British harbor trusts, are self- perpetuating. But the savings banks of New England and New York are supposed to be managed solely for the benefit of de- positors, without stockholders to draw dividends and without profit to the directors. The Consumers' Gas Trust Company of Indianapolis was a venture along similar lines. This company was organized a number of years ago to supply consumers with natural gas at cost. The stockholders agreed to be satisfied with fixed dividends and control of the company was vested in a self- perpetuating board of trustees who managed the business in the interest of consumers, just as a British harbor trust manages a port in the interest of the shippers and vesselmen. This Indian- apolis arrangement was a marked success while it lasted and was terminated only because of the exhaustion of the natural gas supply. Another company has since been formed and au- thorized to engage in the artificial gas business in Indianapolis 42 on the same lines. Under its franchise this company agrees, when the stockholders have been repaid, with interest, to convey the gas plant to the city, to be owned and operated or leased by it. Mayor Dunne's so-called "contract plan" for dealing with the Chicago street railway question was similar in essence to the British harbor trust plan, the difference being that the "con- tract plan" sought to vest control in trustees that should be self-perpetuating. The plan of street railway management which Mayor Johnson tried without success to install in Cleve- land was the same in essence as Mayor Dunne's "contract plan." While the harbor trust plan has worked remarkably well in Great Britain, there seems little likelihood of its receiving ser- ious consideration in this country. That leaves public owner- ship as the only alternative to the various forms of private own- ership and of these alternatives, on the question of ultimate pol- icy, the choice seems clearly to lie on the side of public owner- ship. Public ownership is of two kinds state and municipal. New York's docks are municipal, while those of New Orleans and San Francisco are administered by boards appointed by the gov- ernor of the state. The move toward public ownership in other American ports usually takes the form of municipal ownership. Examples are Baltimore, Philadelphia, Los Angeles and Oakland. Public ownership of docks in Boston, under present tendencies, means state ownership. The Harbor Commissioners of Montreal are a creature of the Dominion or federal government. Chi- cago's docks, if public, would naturally be municipal, as it is the policy in this community to have such matters attended to by the municipal rather than the state authorities. Franchise Possibilities Considered. While the decision with reference to dock management must be in favor of the policy of ultimate municipal ownership, the question as to whether the docks shall be built and owned at the outset by the city or by a corporation acting as the agent of the city is one of business judgment to be decided according to the facts of the concrete situation presented. The ability of 43 the city to borrow money at lower rates of interest than can a private corporation constitutes a strong argument in favor of city ownership at the outset. Then, too, this process actually in- sures city ownership, whereas, if the docks once pass into private hands, the practical difficulty in actually securing control of them at any given time in the future may be great, whatever the legal and theoretical possibilities of municipal acquisition may be. On the other hand, with the borrowing power of the city limited, it may be desired to use the available bond issues for other purposes. Some citizens doubtless would prefer that public money be not risked in an undertaking that might be deemed to have hazards. Such citizens will argue that the in- terests desiring additional dockage facilities, or willing to pro- vide them, should be allowed to take the initial steps on private capital, leaving the city in a position to come into possession later. The decision of the question is likely to be influenced much by the kind of terms which a responsible private corpora- tion desiring to go into the dock business may be willing to offer. I have found little in the experience of other ports to throw light on the question as to what kind of an arrangement should be made with a private corporation, in case it should be deemed advisable to provide for initial development on a franchise basis. The leasing of docks existing and owned by a city does not fur- nish a parallel to the 'situation now confronting Chicago, in which it is proposed that a private corporation be authorized to build docks where none whatever exist at present. Privately owned docks as a rule are held under absolute title of owner- ship. However, I take it that Chicago does not intend at this day to permit new dock development in public waters on any such basis. The effort of the city of Cleveland to work out an arrange- ment with a boat company for the improvement of piers on the lake front of that city may have some suggestive value for Chi- cago. The city of Cleveland owns a small pier projecting into the lake, that is of little use at the present time. It was planned to lease this pier for thirty-five years. Although the lease was to be made only after taking competitive bids, it was expected that the Detroit and Cleveland Navigation Company would se- 44 cure the pier. The understanding was that this company should advance to the city $205,000 to be used for building the pier and the superstructure and also to do some street paving. At the end of the thirty-five years the pier was to be the absolute property of the city, with all the improvements thereon. The company was to agree to keep the property in such condition that it would be worth 70 per cent, of its reconstruction cost. The size of the pie* was to be 750 feet wide and 300 feet long. The city under the ordinance as passed by the council was to reserve the right "to terminate and revoke any such lease, with suitable compen- sation to the lessee, should the city at any time desire to change the use of this property, to reorganize the harbor facilities of the city, to construct lake front boulevards or parks, or to carry out any other public purposes, upon giving two years' notice of the intention of the city so to do." The carrying through of this leasing arrangement has been blocked "temporarily by the refusal of the railroads to agree to make switch track connec- tions with the proposed dock, as the boat interests are unwill- ing to go ahead without assurances upon the point of proper switch track connections. Features of Traction Franchise Policy. If it be decided to permit dock development under a fran- chise arrangement, more light may be gained on this point from an examination of Chicago's own experience with other public utilities, especially the street railways, than is to be secured from a study of ports elsewhere. The main features of Chicago's franchise policy as worked out in the traction settlement ordinances are: (1) The reserva- tion to the city of the right to terminate the grant at any time for purchase by the city or by a licensee corporation; (2) the effort to eliminate speculative profits; (3) full publicity of the affairs of the grantee corporation; (4) participation by the city in the planning and execution of the work of reconstruction. Of these four features, the first named is the most vital, although all are important and would seem to be applicable to the dock situation. 45 The traction question was before the community a long time before it was disposed of, and the features of policy underlying the final settlement received long and careful consideration. The report of the Street Railway Commission submitted to the city council in December, 1900, outlined and discussed the principal features of policy later incorporated in the traction settlement ordinances, devoting special attention to the most vital one, that of the duration of grants. The discussion by the Street Railway Commission of that feature of policy (though consid- ered in that report chiefly in relation to street railways) enunci- ates principles so pertinent to the present dock situation that I reproduce that portion of the document in question as an appen- dix to this report. If the argument of the Street Railway Commission on this point needed support it might be found in the language of the following excerpt from the opinion of the Supreme Court of the United States in the celebrated case of the people against the Illinois Central Railroad, involving claims, to the Chicago lake front : "It is hardly conceivable that the Legislature can divest the state of the control and management of this harbor (Chicago) and vest it abso- lutely in a private corporation. Surely an act of the Legislature transfer- ring the title to its submerged lands and the power claimed by the railroad company to a foreign state or nation, would be repudiated without hesita- tion as a gross perversion of the trust over the property under which it is held. So would a similar transfer to a corporation of another state. It would not be listened to that the control and management of the harbor of that great city a subject of concern to the whole people of the United States should thus be placed elsewhere than in the state itself. All the objections which can be urged to such attempted transfer may be urged to a transfer to a private corporation like the railroad company in this case. Any grant of this kind is necessarily revocable and the exercise of a trust by which the property was held by the state can be resumed at any time. Undoubtedly there may be expenses incurred in improvements made under such a grant, which the state ought to pay; but, be that as it may, the power to resume the trust whenever the state judges best is, we think, in- controvertible. The position advanced by the railroad company in support of its claim to the ownership of the submerged lands and the right to the erection of wharves, piers and docks at its pleasure, or for its business in the harbor of Chicago, would place every harbor in the country at the mercy of a majority of the Legislature of the state in which the harbor is 46 situated. We cannot, it is true, cite any authority where a grant of this kind has been held invalid, for we believe that no instance exists _where the harbor of a great city and its commerce have been allowed to pass into the control of any private corporation. But the decisions are numerous which declare that such property is held by the state, by virtue of its sovereignty in trust for the public. The ownership of the navigable waters of the harbor and of the lands under them is a subject of public concern to the whole people of the state. The trust with which they are held, there- fore, is governmental, and cannot be alienated except in those instances mentioned of parcels used in the improvement of the interest thus held, or when parcels can be disposed of without detriment to the public interest in the lands and waters remaining. This follows necessarily from the public character of the property, being held by the whole people for purposes in which the whole people are interested." The Nature of Chicago's Terminal Problem. Aside from the broad considerations of policy applying to public utility grants generally, there is a special reason why the arrangement with a private company (if one should be entered into) for the construction and ownership of docks north of the mouth of the Chicago river should be subject to termination at any time. No one with faith in the future water commerce of Chicago can believe that the docks in question will be adequate for future needs. It will be necessary to provide additional facilities in some other part of the city. Where, it is difficult to say at this time. The problem calls for further study, separately and in connection with the railroad terminal problem and the proposed Lakes-to-the-Gulf waterway. Chicago's railroad terminal prob- lem calls for a thorough-going expert inquiry in the near future. The general assembly of Illinois will not display wisdom if it proceeds to spend $20,000,000 to promote waterway development without inquiring what the connecting outlet into Lake Michigan is to be. The present Chicago river cannot be considered a satis- factory outlet. Possibly a careful inquiry into this subject would lead to indorsement of the suggestion of Lyman E. Cooley for a new connecting channel between the Sanitary District canal and Lake Michigan in the vicinity of Twenty-second street. In that event the further suggestion of Mr. Cooley that Chicago's future 47 harbor development should be along the Sanitary District canal might also meet with approval. The suggestion of Mr. Isham Randolph (made in connection with his recommendation for a lake front harbor), that the right of way of the old Illinois and Michigan canal be utilized as the roadbed of a belt railroad joining the harbor and the railroads, would fit in admirably with the Cooley suggestion, if the latter be found by expert inquiry to be feasible. The problem of proper dock developments in this commun- ity presents many difficulties, complexities and uncertainties, and is closely related to other unsolved problems, especially that of proper rearrangement of railroad terminals. An era of recon- struction and of tremendous improvement is believed to be di- rectly ahead for Chicago. Nothing should be done that cannot be made to fit into whatever larger plan may be worked out. No rights should be created that will stand as a bar to later -unity. If the docks under discussion are to be built and owned by a private corporation, it should be only on condition that the owners stand ready to sell at any time to the city or to another licensee corporation, thus making it possible to correlate the docks with other related undertakings, whenever plans for de- velopment on a harmonious scale may be worked out. The Com- mercial Club, in its report on a plan of Chicago (page 65), sug- gested that the proposed freight center, the harbors and the connecting transportation systems should be welded together into one complete machine for doing the transportation busi- ness of Chicago "all probably to be owned jointly by some general utility corporation." This suggestion of the Commercial Club" report bears considerable resemblance to the recommenda- tion of the Massachusetts Improvements Commission for a cor- poration representing the railroads and the Commonwealth to develop and control the dock and terminal facilities of Boston. Chicago should retain the power to make docks hereafter or- ganized become a part of this general utility project, whenever it may be realized. It would seem that not much financial risk should be in- volved in connection with the construction of the proposed docks north of the mouth of the river. Most of the boat lines 48 are anxious to go there, provided the proper facilities be ar- ranged for. The term proper facilities would include satisfac- tory switch track and street car service. When the plans have been prepared and estimates of cost made, the boat line managers can be called in and asked what rent they are willing to pay for assignments of space. The leasing contracts could be entered into in advance of the beginning of construction. 49 II. LEASING POLICY, Under the head of leasing policy will be discussed the var- ious arrangements under which boats are permitted to use dock facilities. These various arrangements may be divided into three main classifications. First, there is the leasing system, as practiced in New York city, under which boat lines make definite leases of dock space for fixed periods and during the life of the lease have the ex- clusive control of the particular dock space specified. Then there is the system in use in New Orleans, under which the charges are based on the tonnage capacity of the vessel, without regard to the quantity of goods moved over the wharf. New Orleans makes no charge whatever against the goods, but collects its entire revenue from the ship owner. Galveston and Montreal furnish examples of the third sys- tem, under which no charge is levied against the vessel, but the entire revenues are raised by a schedule of dues on the com- modities moving over the wharf. Some ports have a combination of two or more of these sys- tems. In San Francisco, for example, there is a charge on both vessel and goods. In addition to the three types of charges above mentioned, there is often a special charge for the use of sheds, either in the i'orm of sheddage dues or of fixed rental for the use of shed facilities. The storage charge on goods left on the pier longer than specified periods of time is in its nature akin to the storage charge imposed by warehouse concerns. 51 The New Orleans system of charges against the vessel ac- cording to tonnage capacity is unusual in this country, but is more common in foreign ports. The effect of its operation is supposed to be to make the port more attractive to shippers of goods, inasmuch as the goods are made to bear no wharfage charges whatever. The system in use in Galveston and Mon- treal, on the other hand, is designed to attract vessel owners to the port inasmuch as it imposes no burdens upon them what- ever. Supposedly, however, in the long run, conditions are equalized in the rates for transportation of the carriers, both rail and water. Pier Using Privileges Revocable. Eegular line vessels doing business in the port of New Or- leans have definite dock space assigned to them which is held for them exclusively so long as they are able to make full use of the space. It is the policy of the port authorities of New Orleans to give boat companies no contract rights for fixed per- iods of time for the use of dock space. Assignments of space or agreements for the use thereof are subject to revocation by the port authorities at any time. In case berth space which has been assigned to a particular boat company is hot occupied by the boats of that company at any given time, the port authori- ties reserve the right to dock some other vessel at that point and this right is frequently exercised. Where shed facilities are furnished there is an additional charge based likewise upon the tonnage of the vessel. In cases where the port authority was unable to provide sheds and the boat companies advanced the funds, they were given in return preferential rights to the dock space in question until such time as the loan, without interest, should be repaid, all of the sheddage charge and 25 per cent, of the wharfage charge being devoted to such repayment. Galveston and Montreal have schedules of charges for mov- ing goods across the wharf, either to or from the boat, that are much like the tariff schedules of a railroad company. These schedules provide for different rates for different classes of goods. The charge on cotton, for example, in Galveston, is 1J cents per 100 pounds. In both Galveston and Montreal, as in 52 New Orleans, definite assignments of space are made to regular boat lines, but none of these assignments has a fixed tiffieTlura- tion. They are revocable at the will of the port authority and where the space is not utilized to the full limit of its capacity the port management reserves the right to put in other vessels. There are special charges on a, rental basis on account of shed- dage. The charges collected by the port authority of San Francisco are termed dockage, tolls, and wharfage. Dockage is the charge against a vessel for occupying a berth. The rates vary according to the class and size of the vessel. Tolls are the charges made for merchandise passing over the state wharves. The rate is 5 cents a ton, except on a few commodities such as lumber and brick, for which there are different rates. Wharfage in the port of San Francisco is defined as the charge made for leaving mer- chandise on state premises longer than the time specified in the rules. In most ports this is called storage and the term wharf- age is used to define what are called tolls in San Francisco. As in New Orleans, Galveston and Montreal, so it is the policy of the port authorities in San Francisco to make no assignments of space and to give no rights of occupation or use of piers that are not revocable at any time. Recently an exception has been made to this policy as a means of securing the construction of much needed sheds with the aid of private capital. Where the lessee of a dock would agree to put up a shed with his own money, the harbor authorities have given definite term leases, not to exceed fifteen years in length, on condition that the shed become the property of the harbor commissioners at the ex- piration of the lease. While the charges made by the harbor commissioners in the port of San Francisco are very moderate, the pilotage dues and the stevedoring and teaming charges are so heavy as to make the handling of goods through the port of San Francisco rather expensive. In Seattle, Vancouver, Tacoma and Portland the schedules of charges are very simple. The prevailing rate on commodities for the privilege of using the wharf is 50 cents a ton, with no charges 53 against the vessel. Different rates are provided for special classes of commodities. In many cases the boat line owns or leases its pier, or if it is engaged in interchange traffic with. a railroad, uses the railroad company's pier. In Boston, Phila- delphia, Baltimore, Norfolk arid in the lake cities the boat lines commonly use railroad piers or own or lease their piers and such charges as dockage or wharfage do not appear. The Policy of Railroads as Pier Owners. Where a railroad company owns dock facilities there is com- monly no charge whatever, either against the boat or upon the goods that have a rail haul. But upon goods not having a rail haul there is a toll or wharfage charge just as there is in Gal- veston. The charges imposed by a railroad company upon goods not having a rail haul are likely to be rather high. The railroad companies doing business in San Francisco absorb the toll of 5 cents a ton on commodities carried by rail to or from competi- tive railroad points. To non-competitive points the railroads terminating in San Francisco do not, absorb the toll imposed on the goods by the harbor commissioners of San Francisco, but add the toll to the freight rate. Passenger boats doing an extensive business ordinarily have leasing arrangements for the use of the pier space which they require. The lesser excursion boats are commonly charged so much a day or a month or a season, the charge being based roughly on the size of the boat and the amount of business done. New York's Pier Leasing Policy. I have reserved the New York situation for separate and more extended treatment because it seems to serve as an exam- ple of unwise policy. There are a few "open" piers in New York city, usually un- shedded, at which boats may tie up and load or unload upon the payment of wharfage. These piers are few in number and are used for the most part only by canal boats and sailing vessels. Steamboats would not think of depending upon the open piers in New York city for accommodations. Nearly all the munic- 54 ipal piers in New York harbor are used under leases of varying terms and conditions. From the establishment of the dock department in 1870, to 1902, pier leases were made by the board of dock commissioners, consisting first of five and later of three members. By charter legislation of 1901, effective January 1, 1902, the dock depart- ment was made a single headed department. The commissioner of docks was authorized to make pier leases, but leases of more than one year's duration must have the approval of the board of sinking fund commissioners. Neither the board of aldermen nor the board of estimate and apportionment have anything to do with pier leasing policy. Revocable permits and leases for Jess than a year are made by the. dock commissioner on his own authority. Pier leases, once obtained, may be transferred or sublet with the sanction of the dock commissioner. There is no requirement for publicity with reference to sub-leases or transfers. The dock commissioner in practice ordinarily gives his consent without knowing the detailed terms of the sub-lease or transfer. Speculative traffic in leases might be going on for all the dock commissioner or the public is aware. It is gossip that there is much speculation in leases and that fortunate in- dividuals or companies make large sums of money by transfer- ring at large advances leases to municipal piers. The law pro- vides that leases may be made for ten year periods with the privilege in the lessee of not to exceed four renewals of ten years each, or fifty years in all. The leases must be let by public auc- tion unless the board by unanimous consent decides that com- petitive leasing is not expedient. In practice, public letting "has almost entirely disappeared. In the history of the dock department there have been very few instances of fifty year leases of water front property and these were for industrial rather than for navigation purposes. The leases to boat lines are ordinarily of twenty years' or thirty years' duration that is, a ten year lease with the right to a re- newal of one or two periods of ten years each. There seems to be no settled basis of ascertaining the amount of rental to be charged for piers. As a matter of fact the rates of rental for piers of substantially the same value vary widely. 55 It is impossible to avoid the conclusion that influence, polit- ical and otherwise, has been a factor in the leasing policy of the New York Dock Department. Moreover, this influence has been exerted at times in a manner detrimental to the interests of shipping and of the public. The most conspicuous instance is afforded by the ice trust scandals of the Van Wyck administration. It was largely through the favoritism of the dock department that the so-called ice trust was enabled to get such a strong hold upon the situation at that time. Many instances can be cited of politicians securing leases to pier space devoted to dump uses for less than market value of the space. If such leases, instead of being definite term con- tracts for fixed periods of considerable length, were revocable at will, any serious abuses that might develop could be easily remedied. Case of the Enterprise Transportation Company. The possibility of favoritism by the dock department may signify much with reference to the matter of railroad control of water transportation. Under the Van Wyck administration, Charles W. Morse, then at the head of the ice trust and also in- terested in many boat companies, seemed to be able to get a large number of leases for the boat companies in which he was interested. Under the present administration the remnant of the Morse boat holdings appear to have difficulty in securing pier accommodations. The New York, New Haven and Hart- ford Eailroad Company, which how controls all the steamship lines operating on Long Island Sound except the Morse line, the Metropolitan SteamsSip Company, operating the Harvard and the Yale between Boston and New York direct, has of late been securing, either directly or through its constituent companies, a considerable number of leases to desirable dock property. It looks very much as if the New York dock department, whether knowingly or unknowingly is not for me to say, has pursued a policy that was calculated to enable the New York, New Haven and Hartford Railroad Company to drive competitors out of business. The history of the Enterprise Transportation Company 56 serves to substantiate this statement. This was a small company that undertook to conduct a transportation lme~ be- tween New York and Boston, by way of Fall River. The Enter- prise Transportation Company had the very greatest difficulty in getting dock accommodations of any kind in New York city. One pier that it had was taken away from it for purposes of re- construction. It then sought to secure a lease to the newly con- structed Pier 28 in the East river. The pier which it desired was, on June 20, 1906, leased to the Joy Steamship Company, a New York, New Haven and Hartford concern, for $42,000 a year. This is by far the highest rental paid for pier space on the East river and amounts to more per square foot than is paid in most instances on the North river, where dock space is sup- posed to be much more valuable. After the pier had been leased to the Joy Steamship Company it laid practically unused for a long time, thus tending to substantiate the accusation that the high rental was paid by the New York, New Haven and Hart- ford interests, not for the use of the pier, but to prevent its use by a rival. After much difficulty the Enterprise company managed to lease, at a large rental, half a pier from another con- cern that did not need all its space. The Enterprise Transporta- tion Company continued in business for some time and main- tained considerably lower rates, both for passengers and freight, than the competing boats of the New York, New Haven and Hartford Railroad Company's boat lines, thus benefiting ship- pers. But it had to meet the continued opposition of the rail- road interests in many ways. For instance, the New York, New Haven and Hartford steamship lines could get a through rate with the Pennsylvania Company much lower than could be se- cured over the Enterprise route. This matter was several times called to the attention of the Interstate Commerce Commission, which body in one of its reports said : "In an investigation entitled 'In the matter of alleged discrimination against the Enterprise Transportation Company b.y railroad lines leading from New York City 7 (11 I. C. C. Kep. 587) it was shown that railroad lines west from New York City made joint through rates with the New England Navigation Company, controlling the Fall River line of steamers, which plies between New York and Fall River, Mass., and some other New Eng- land cities, and also controlling other important steamer lines operating on 57 Long Island Sound. Such joint rates applied in both directions between Western and New England points. The New England Navigation Company is owned and operated by the New York, New Haven and Hartford Bail- road Company. The rail lines centering in New York and running westerly thereof refused, for stated business reasons, to make the like or any joint rating arrangement with the Enterprise Transportation Company, a steam- ship line pyling between Fall River and other New England points and New York City and in competition with the New England Navigation Com- pany's Fall Eiver line. "It appeared that the Fall River line might, by reducing rates on local traffic force out of business the Enterprise Transportation Company, while obtaining a lucrative and supporting business from the through traffic, and upon disappearance of such competition restore the former charges. The existence of the Enterprise Transportation Company as a competitive factor was of distinct value to the public, and that existence might depend upon its right to engage in through business. This investigation was made by the Commission with the understanding that it was without power to grant any relief, and no opinion as to whether the through routing arrange- ment should have been extended to the Enterprise Transportation Company was expressed; but the Commission expressed the opinion that if the pub- lic is to have the legitimate benefit of water competition it is evident that authority should be provided to establish through routes between rail and water carriers, or at least to prevent unjust discrimination by rail carriers between connecting water lines." After the amendment of the Interstate Commerce law this charge of discrimination against the Enterprise Transportation Company was again brought before the Interstate Commerce. Commission and an order was issued requiring the Pennsylvania railroad to make reasonable through route and joint rate ar- rangements with the Enterprise Company. But before this or- der actually became operative the Enterprise Company gave up the struggle and went out of business in the fall of 1907. On the very same day on which Pier 28 in the East river was leased by the dock authorities to the Joy Steamship Company at an exceptionally high rental, thus keeping it out of the hands of the Enterprise Transportation Company, the dock authorities made leases of valuable dock space in the North river to certain transatlantic lines and justified the very low rental on the grounds that it was the duty of the dock authorities to encour- age commerce. But vessel interests engaged in coastwise ship- 58 ping business in opposition to railroad controlled boats have not shared in that encouragement. It is predicted by some that the Metropolitan Steamship Company, not under railroad con- trol, will have very great difficulty in securing dock accommo- dations in New York harbor next year unless it makes terms with the New York, New Haven and Hartford railroad interests. The Evil of Definite Term Leases. The greatest objection to private ownership of dock facilities is that the private owners may use their control to suppress competition and promote monopoly. A study of the New York situation indicates that public ownership under the system of long term leases may be productive of the same evil, but to a lesser degree. Private ownership, being perpetual, would tend to make the abuses perpetual. But under public ownership, and with the leasing system in use in New York city, the leases will expire in twenty or thirty years at the outside and thus enable the public in the course of time to regain control. If all leases to piers in the harbor of New T York were subject to revocation at any time, as is the policy in New Orleans, San Francisco, Montreal, Liverpool, Glasgow and many other European ports, the evils I have pointed out in the New York situation would not develop, or if they did, could be easily remedied. The railroads are popularly supposed to be very influential in. the politics of California, yet I was unable to find any criticism that the Har- bor Commissioners in San Francisco, where pier leases are revoc- able at will, have used their power to suppress independent boat lines engaged in business in competition with railroad-owned boat lines, although the struggle of the railroads for the control of all coastwise shipping business is in evidence on the Pacific as well as on the Atlantic seacoast. The pier space in New York is not utilized to the best ad- vantage. The railroads have more of the pier space than they really need. Several boat lines have piers devoted to their own exclusive use and do not have the business to keep the piers occupied all the time. Many of these piers could accommodate more boats. Yet, while this is true, shipping is kept out of New York city because of inability to secure dock facilities. This is 59 especially true of boats that would like to engage in the coast- wise traffic. If all leases to municipal piers in the harbor of New York were revocable at any time, as in New Orleans, San Francisco and Montreal, the harbor authorities could make a rearrangement which would permit the accommodation of boat lines that are now excluded. As Chicago's study of the street railroad question led to the conclusion that all franchises to street railway companies should be subject to termination at any time, so a study of the dock problem here and elsewhere must lead to the conclusions : First, that if the docks are developed and owned in first instance by a private corporation, the franchise should be subject to termina- tion at any time; and second, that the leases to the boat com- panies for dock space should likewise be subject to revocation at any time, or on short notice. The only excuse offered in New York for leases of twenty years' or thirty years' duration is that the lessee usually is re- quired to build a shed upon the pier and that as the shed, at the end of the lease, becomes the property of the city, the lessee must have a sufficient guaranteed time to insure his getting his value out of the shed. There are two ways of meeting this ob- jection. Either the city should build the shed as well as the dock in first instance, or the city in reserving the right to term- inate the lease should provide for reasonable payment to the lessee on account of the shed, in case of revocation. Recommendation for Chicago. Possibly at the outset in Chicago it might be expedient to compromise and provide that leases should have ten years of definite duration and after that be subject to revocation at will. Baltimore started out with the policy of making fifty year leases. As in New York, this policy was justified because the lessee erected the shed and it was deemed necessary on this ac- count to give long guaranteed time to enable the lessee to get the value of his shed back. The engineer in charge of harbor work announces that he intends to recommend city construction of sheds as well as piers in the future, thus doing away with the necessity for long term leases. Outside of New York and Balti- 60 more, leases of definite term duration generally are for periods of not more than twenty years and frequently the period is much shorter than twenty years. In Boston private dock owners in numerous cases make twenty year leases. The arrangements which the Boston and Maine railroad make with boat companies for the use of docks are generally limited to five years. The Massachusetts Harbor and Land Commissioners make no leases of dock space for longer than fifteen years. In Seattle the North- ern Pacific Railroad Company makes twenty year leases, but provides for revaluation and change of rental every five years. The Canadian Pacific Railroad Company in Vancouver makes twenty year leases which are subject to termination at the will of the company. The leasing arrangements of the Chicago, Mil- waukee and S>t. Paul railroad with the boat companies for the use of railroad docks in the port of Milwaukee are usually for five year periods. The Bush Terminal Company in New York makes no leases for longer than ten years. It is argued by offi- cials of this company that ten years is about as long as condi- tions can be foreseen with any degree of accuracy. Whatever leasing policy the city might deem wise for itself it would naturally expect a corporation developing docks under a franchise to follow. If the rights of shippers and vesselmen are to be safeguarded under a system of private ownership of docks, provision must be made for continuing public control of dock management, including supervision of leasing policy. I have assumed that the system of leasing pier space to boat owners, as distinguished from systems of dockage or wharfage charges, would be followed in Chicago, as that system is the simplest and is the one with which the shipping interests of the Great Lakes are most familiar. It should be the policy of the city, however, to have at all times some unleased pier space at which occasional boats may load and unload. For the use of such piers it would be most convenient, perhaps, to provide a schedule of wharfage dues, after the manner of Galveston, im- posing a charge of so much a ton on goods moved over the pier. For passenger boats not having regular leased pier space it would be necessary to devise a system of charges based probably on the size of the boat. 61 m. THE IMPORTANCE TO CHICAGO OF THE PAS- SENGER, PACKAGE FREIGHT, AND FRUIT AND VEGETABLE BUSINESS. Although considerable attention was given to this phase of the subject in the report of the Harbor Commission, it may be well to point out again in the present connection the importance to Chicago of the passenger, package freight, and fruit and veg- etable business. In earlier stages of development the great raw materials and bulk commodities constitute the larger part of the water traffic of any port. But as communities progress other forms of traffic grow in comparative importance. Chicago could have a much lager water traffic in the miscel- laneous cargo line if it would but provide better accommoda- tions for handling such articles of commerce. Better facilities, no doubt, would greatly encourage passenger traffic on the lakes. The development of such traffic signifies much for the health and pleasure of our own inhabitants and makes the city a much more attractive place for visitors. Better facilities for handling fruit and vegetables are sorely needed in Chicago. Increase of traffic and better service to con- sumers should follow improvement of facilities for handling this class of business. Some figures may help us to understand the importance of the package, or unclassified freight movement. The freight movement of 81,000,000 tons on the Great Lakes in 1907 is classi- fied approximately as follows : 63 Per cent. Iron ore and other minerals (except coal) 58 Lumber Grain and grain products 7 Hard coal 5 Soft coal 19 Unclassified, including merchandise, fruits and vegetables 8 Total 100 It will be seen from the foregoing table that for the Great Lakes as a whole the percentage of unclassified freight is greater than that of hard coal, grain and grain products, or lumber. For Chicago the percentage of unclassified freight to the total freight handled in the port is higher than that for the Great Lakes as an entirety. The receipts and shipments of the port of Chicago (including both the Chicago and Calumet harbors) for 1907 were 11,410,470 net tons. Of this sum the receipts were 8,564,754 and the shipments 2,845,716 net tons. The receipts and shipments by water in the port of Chicago in the year 1907 may be classi- fied in percentages as follows : Receipts, Shipments, per cent. per cent. Iron ore and other minerals (except coal) . . 62.35 .63 Lumber 8.58 .07 Grain and grain products 21 72.00 Coal (both hard and soft) 16.51 4.03 Unclassified 12.35 23.27 Total 100.00 100.00 The following extract from the report submitted by me to the Chicago Harbor Commission last year gives some figures designed to indicate that the unclassified freight movement is of much more value than might be inferred from the compara- tive tonnage statistics : "With respect to lines of lake commerce, Chicago f s interest would seem to lie most in the direction of increasing the package freight or mis- cellaneous cargo business. "Iron ore, which constitutes about one-half the total tonnage of lake commerce, is little seen in the Chicago harbor. Nor do we care for it there. The great blast furnaces do not belong in the center of the city. They are 64 better located for all concerned where they are, at South Chicago, Indiana Harbor and Gary. "Chicago is still the world's greatest lumber market, although the arrivals by water have greatly decreased. The water business is stiH of im- portance, however, and many lumbermen think the present volume of busi- ness may be maintained for a generation or more. At any rate, it is im- portant that the city have facilities for handling such quantity of lumber as may continue to come here, even though no increase may be looked for, owing to the disappearance of the timber supply at points available for water transportation. '.The place where the lumber is wanted appears to be the Chicago river and not the Calumet. For the year 1907 Chicago re- ceived in round numbers 2,400,000,000 feet of lumber, of which 400,000,000 feet, or one-sixth, came by water. Not many years ago the receipts of lum- ber by water greatly exceeded those by rail. "The coal unloading facilities in the Chicago river are not as good as at other leading lake ports. Perhaps they are as good as are warranted by the condition of the harbor. Eiver improvement might be expected to lead to the introduction of better unloading facilities. While the Calumet river may answer as a trans-shipping point, it cannot meet the needs of Chicago proper as a receiving point for coal for consumption in this city. "The number of grain elevators on the Chicago river is growing smal- ler. As elevators have been destroyed by fire or other cause they have not been rebuilt. The center of the wheat trade is moving westward and north- ward away from Chicago. The city, however, while it does not lead in wheat, is still the world's greatest grain market. The center of the corn supply is not likely to move away. Much of the grain storage of the city is on the Calumet river. Except for one consideration it might be a matter of indifference to the community at large whether the grain center be on one river or the other, apart from the question of preserving investments already made. That consideration has to do with the encouragement of the package freight business. While the total volume of freight east is greater than the volume west, more package freight moves west than east. The package boats, therefore, need grain cargoes east, in part at least. And as most of the package freight comes into Chicago rather than the Calumet river, it is highly important that there be elevators in the Chicago harbor to supply the package boats with their return cargoes of grain. These boats would find it disadvantageous to be obliged to go to South Chicago for grain, especially for partial cargoes, after unloading in the Chicago river. This constitutes an argument for encouraging at least a considerable number of grain elevators to stay in the Chicago harbor. "Because iron ore, grain, coal and lumber constitute the principal vol- ume by weight of lake commerce, it is assumed in some quarters that they alone are worthy of serious consideration. The package freight or miscel- laneous carim business, however, is of very great importance. The great 65 dry goods and grocery houses of Chicago actually bring in enormous quanti- ties of merchandise by water. The ability to do so constitutes the principal reason for the pre-eminence of this city as a wholesale and jobbing center. It is difficult to obtain precise information as to the volume and value of this traffic, because facts of this nature are not freely given to the public by concerns engaged in keen competition with one another. "From the record and decision of the Interstate Commerce Commission in the case of Wyman, Partridge & Co. and others against certain lake and rail carriers, docket No. 1126, certain specific information is obtainable with reference to the business of Wyman, Partridge & Co. of Minneapolis and Marshall Field & Co. of Chicago. For the year 1905 the latter firm brought into Chicago by lake approximately 18,000 tons of merchandise, having an invoice value at points of shipment of about $12,000,000. The lake and rail receipts of Wyman, Partridge & Co. for the same year were 6,000 tons, of an invoice value of $3,000,000. "The receipts of unclassified freight in the port of Chicago including Chicago and South Chicago for the year 1905 were 1,098,054 tons. The shipments were 640,042 tons. Of the receipts of 1,098,054 tons, the 18,000 tons belonging to Marshall Field & Co. represented a value of $12,000,000. The total hard coal receipts at Chicago and South Chicago for the year 1905 were 884,057 net tons. At Buffalo September prices, $4.91 a ton, this coal was worth $4,330,719.87, or only a little more than one-third the invoice value of Marshall Field's receipts by lake for the same year. The wheat shipments by lake from Chicago for 1905 were small, only 5,498,868 bushels. But the larger shipments of 1907, 14,448,231 bushels, had less value than the receipts of Marshall Field for 1905. The corn shipments of 1905 were 44,- 939,308 bushels. At 40 cents a bushel the value of this corn would be only about 50 per cent more than the Marshall Field receipts by lake. The lum- ber receipts by lake for 1905 were 423,993 thousand feet. At $20 a thou- sand, a high price, this lumber would have only two-thirds the value of the Marshall Field lake receipts. The iron ore brought into the port in 1905, principally in South Chicago, amounted to 3,324,320 tons. At $2 a ton this ore would have only a little more than half the value of the Marshall Field receipts. "The entire value of Duluth's traffic for 1905 was: ' ' Eeceipts $31,849,509 ' ' Shipments 74,065,789 "Total $105,915,298 "The value figures for Chicago's receipts and shipments are not avail- able, but if they were it is evident that Duluth's commerce', despite its greater tonnage, would be comparatively insignificant in value. "Federal government reports (see Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance) give, estimates of value of traffic through .the Soo. According to these reports, the value of unclassified freight passing through the Soo developed from $18,744,600 in 1889 to $170,227,650 in 1906. The value of the iron ore traffic grew from $14,335,492 in 1889 to $121,981,795 in 1906. In other words, the unclassified freight through the Soo in 1906, of 1,134,- 851 net tons, was worth approximately $48,000,000 more than the 35,357,042 tons of iron ore passing through the same channel. The unclassified freight passing both ways through the Soo is about the same in volume as that entering the port of Chicago. Against the 1,134,850 tons of unclassified freight traffic through the Soo in 1906, Chicago had receipts of 1,035,- 317 tons. For the years 1905 and 1907 Chicago's receipts of unclassified freight exceeded the Soo traffic. It would seem to be a good guess that the unclassified freight received at Chicago would have a higher average value per ton than that passing through the Soo. "Value of the articles handled, as well as tonnage, must be taken into consideration in measuring the value of traffic to a community. ' ' The fruit traffic is one form of the miscellaneous cargo business that is of special importance to Chicago. In most instances rail carriage is con- sidered preferable to water carriage, unless the latter offers lower rates. But for fruit, water carriage is best in cases where the destination can be reached by a night's run. The lack of the jarring motion of the train and the coolness of the water journey cause fruit carried by boat to arrive in better condition. The fruit belt of Michigan is just about a night 's run from Chicago and fruit gathered in the late afternoon can be placed on the dock in Chicago early the next morning, in time for delivery for consump- tion the same day. As has already been indicated, in the discussion of the passenger boat business, the fruit handling facilities in this port leave much to be desired." APPENDIX A. Extract from Report of the Street Railway Com- mission to the City Council of Chicago, December, 1900. PUBLIC CONTROL AND DURATION OF GRANTS. These two matters should be considered together because of the inti- mate relation one bears to the other. The primary object in granting to private corporations the right to encumber the public streets with car tracks is to secure street car service. Unless this primary object is accomplished the street railway policy of the city must be said to be a failure, no matter how large revenues may be secured for the public treasury, nor how advantageous for the city the terms of a franchise grant may be in other respects. How to secure ade- quate service at reasonable rates is, therefore, the essence of the street railway problem. All other considerations, comparatively speaking, are of secondary importance. One way that suggests itself of securing adequate service is to stipu late for it in the franchise. But franchise stipulations of this kind are not self-executing. It is one thing to insert in a grant provisions requirng certain things in the way of service. It is quite another matter actually to get the things done. Moreover, it is absolutely impossible to make stip- ulations today that will fit the changed conditions of tomorrow. No person is wise enough to formulate for insertion into a street railway franchise that is to be interpreted as a contract all the stipulations that will be necessary to insure good service for the period, say, of a generation for which the franchise may run. In fact, the more a street railway franchise partakes of the nature of a contract, which cannot be altered in any material respect except with the consent of both parties, even to meet changes in conditions which could not be foreseen at the time the grant was made, the less satisfactory is it certain to prove in operation and the more is it likely to militate against healthy and progressive development. On the other hand, the more such a franchise partakes of the nature of a mere license, being subject to complete regulation and control by the public authorities at all times, the better for the public at large. Mere property interests of a government, like the property interests of an indi- vidual, may properly enough be contracted away. But governing authori- 69 ties ought not, by contract, to divest themselves of governing functions. Control of the public streets and of the public means of transportation thereon, is a governing function which should, so far as possible, be vested in the proper governing authorities at all times. Such control should be continuous and properly ought not to be surrendered beyond recall, either by contract or in any other manner. But, of course, it is surrendered to a greater or less degree by the ordinary definite term street railway grant with which we are familiar. The present widespread dissatisfaction with street railway management in private hands, it would seem, may in large measure fairly be attributed to the fact that public authorities have not retained continuous control, as they should have done, but have per- mitted themselves to be divested of it by contract. British and German cities generally have a reputation for marked ability in making contracts with public service corporations, and some of the agreements made by those cities, conferring franchise rights, are remarkable for the ingenuity and detail with which they seek to guard against future contingencies. But the results under these very carefully drawn contracts do not seem to be satisfactory, because, as the contract periods expire, British and German cities are rapidly adopting the policy of municipalization. Some contend that the careful restrictions of the contracts made by British and German cities tend to hamper and discourage private enterprise and thus to pre- clude satisfactory street railway development under private management. Whether this or some other explanation be accepted as the correct one, the fact remains that the system of regulation by contract has not proven satisfactory in British and German cities, as attested by the fact that this system is being abandoned with considerable rapidity for the policy of municipalization. Prof. James, of the University of Chicago, who has lately returned from a trip of investigation of German cities, tells an incident which helps to an understanding of the movement toward munic- ipal ownership in Germany. In reply to a question as to the reason why the City of Cologne was proceeding to take over its tramways, the Mayor of that city said to Prof. James: "We are taking over the tramways because it was found impossible thoroughly to safeguard the public inter- ests under any contract with a private corporation that could be drawn." There is unquestionably in American cities a strong popular trend in the direction of municipalization of street railways. It seems also to be unquestionable that the growth of municipalization sentiment is due in large measure to the failure, or supposed failure, of many American cities to get satisfactory results from public service corporations with which they have attempted to deal on the contract basis. One of two things appears to be inevitable. Either a system of really effective continuing public control over street railways must be developed or street railways are virtually certain to be municipalized sooner or later. Manifestly, therefore, it should be the part of those who look with dis- 70 favor upon the idea of municipalization to do what they can to assist in developing a system of control over street railways that will prove satis- factory to the public. In attempting to devise a system of effective public control, the impor- tant considerations are: (1) That adequate powers of control be reserved to the governing authorities to be exercised by such authorities in their discretion at any time; (2) that special machinery be created for the purpose of insuring the intelligent exercise of such powers of control in the interest of the public. As has been said, franchise stipulations designed to insure adequate service are not self executing. There must be some supervising body, whose special business it is to see that the things stipulated are actually done. Moreover, specific franchise stipulations cannot possibly cover all points in relation to service that may arise. The proper governing author- ities should be able at any time to make such regulations, or to order such improvements in service, as the needs of the public may require. Therefore broad powers of control should be reserved to the governing authorities, to be exercised as need may arise. Section 6 of the proposed bill aims to reserve to city councils broader powers of control than are now possessed. If this bill should not become a law before the settlement of the pending franchise-renewal problem, the City Council by all means ought specifically to reserve such powers of control in any grant that may be made. Having reserved the right of control, special governmental machinery for the exercise of such right must be devised if the control is to be really effective and of benefit to the public. Chicago today has rights of control which are not exercised for the lack of any supervising body whose special business it is to recommend regulations for the improve- ment of the service and to see that existing regulations are properly enforced. What should this machinery be? Two plans or methods are naturally suggested for consideration. One is the creation of a Commission to be entirely independent of the Council. The other is to have the desired machinery of control developed within the Council. The Street Eailway Commission gives its approval to the latter plan. It would recommend that a new standing committee of the Council be created, to be known, perhaps, as the Committee on Local Transporta- tion. This committee in many respects might well be modeled after the Track Elevation Committee. It should not be large in number. It should have regular quarters in the City Hall, which should at all times during business hours be open for receiving complaints concerning service from citizens, and for the imparting of information. This committee should have such expert and clerical assistants as might be required. These assistants 71 should be under the protection of the civil service law, to the end that their tenure of employment should be permanent or during good behavior, in order that the city may have the benefit of their experience after they have become familiar with the problems to be dealt with. The most important feature of this plan is the one providing that the Council, through its committee on this subject, should have at its service a per- manent force of experts 'to advise and assist it in dealing with the various problems of local transportation as they may arise. Naturally, too, this same committee, with its expert advisers and its mass of accumulated information and experience, is the one to which ordinances conferring the right to construct or operate street railways would be referred. This committee, acting for the Council, would be better qualified to conduct the preliminary negotiations with a private corpora- tion over franchise terms than would a committee that is only occasionally called upon to consider street railway matters. The present plan of referring street railway ordinances to one of three committees (Streets and Alleys, West, North or South, as the case may be), according to the part of the city in which it may be proposed to locate the road, is espe- cially objectionable as tending to foster the sectionalism which it should be the object of a well considered street railway policy to obliterate. If the street railway systems of the city ought to be unified as far as possible, and the Commisison believes they should be, the City Council itself ought to take the first step in that direction, by having one committee to con- sider all street railway matters, rather than three committees, made up on strictly sectional lines, as is the case at present. All Grants Should Expire Together. In order for the city to control the situation satisfactorily it must be able to deal with the problem as an entirety at any given time, which it is not in a position to do when some outstanding grants expire at one time and some at other times. It ought to be the policy of the city in the future, therefore, to make provision to have all grants expire at the same time. This is a matter of much importance. Duration of Grants. It was said at the opening of the discussion under this heading that the question of duration of grants was closely related to the problem of public control. The nature of that relation will now be considered. As has already been stated, efforts to control public service corpora- tions through contractual agreements generally have proven unsatisfactory wherever tried, whether in this country or in Europe. The Commission, in the plan recommended for the reservation of broad powers of control, hopes to secure better results than can possibly be secured through con- tract stipulations in the franchise with reference to service. But the 72 Commission does not delude itself with the hope that the results under .this plan will be entirely satisfactory and perhaps they may not in practice prove even approximately so. It is difficult to compel a corporation enjoy- ing definite term rights in the public streets to do what it may desire for reasons of self-interest not to do. The only way for the city to be certain of its ability to exercise complete control over its public streets and over the means of transportation thereon is for it not to surrender beyond recall any rights of use or of occupation in such streets. The city can control completely only when it is in a position to terminate at any time the right of use claimed by any person or corporation that may choose to defy the will of the city -in any respect. In other words, the grant terminable at any time at the will of the city authorities is the only kind under which the city can be sure of its ability to dominate the situation at all times. And it is precisely in the communities where that form of grant obtains that the best results generally are secured, and it is in such communities that the relation between the corporations and the public are the most satisfactory. We refer to the State of Massachusetts and to the City of Washington, D. C. In Massachusetts street railway grants do not run for any definite period. A company is simply granted a " location, " that is, it is per- mitted to lay its tracks in a street. But the location may be revoked at any time. Until recently the power of revocation rested absolutely with the local authorities, but the act has lately been amended so as to give the right of appeal to certain state authorities where the company may feel that it has been treated unfairly. But the principle of a grant revocable by the public authorities at will has not been altered. This power of revocation, it is true, has seldom been used, but its existence has served to keep the corporations on their good behavior at all times, and to keep the public authorities complete masters of the situation at all times. Moreover, capital has not been wanting for street railway enter- prises in Massachusetts under these conditions. The only careful and thorough-going official study ever made in this country of the subject of the proper duration of street railway grants, so far as this Commission is aware, was that made by a Massachusetts com- mittee, of which Mr. Charles Francis Adams was chairman. The report of that committee, which was submitted to the legislature of Massachusetts in February, 1898, is so enlightening and instructive that lengthy extracts from it are appended to this report. The Massachusetts committee, after an examination of the different varieties of grant in use, declared in favor of the continuation of the Massachusetts system of indefinite term grants. "In theory," it says, "such a franchise is to the last degree illogical." Yet it cannot be said, the Commission further adds, "that the system has for the half century it has been in use worked otherwise than on the whole satisfactory." On the other hand, the term franchise, where- 73 ever its results were studied, the committee says, "has been productive of dissention, poor service, scandals and unhealthy political action. ' ' The committee adds: "There is probably no possible system productive of only good results and in no respect open to criticism; but, in fairness, the committee found itself forced to conclude that the Massachusetts franchise, which might, perhaps, not improperly be termed a tenure good behavior, would in its practical results compare favorably with any. Certainly those results are as immeasurably as they are undeniably better than the results as yet produced in Great Britain." The important thing in the testimony of the Massachusetts committee is the assertion that the Massachusetts system of indefinite term grants has worked well in practice. It is important to know, too, that the system is satisfactory both to the companies and to the municipalities, for at the hearings of the committee neither asked for any change in the form of franchise grant in this respect, except that the companies suggested some "partial measures of protection against possible orders of sudden, ill-con- sidered or aggressive revocation." Turning to the City of Washington, we find this same indefinite term grant in use, with most satisfactory results. Washington is one of the smaller cities of the country, and therefore does not furnish as profitable a field of operation from the street railway manager's point of view as do the larger centers of population like Chicago, Philadelphia or New York. Nevertheless, Washington has the best street railway service of any city in the country and it has led most other cities in the introduction of improvements in service. In Washington franchise grants are conferred by act of Congress, and all grants are subject to alteration, amendment or repeal at any time, at the will of Congress. Under the power thus reserved Congress orders such improvements in service as it may deem desirable, and whenever it deems them desirable, and the orders are at once executed without parley or litigation. The overhead trolley was never permitted in Washington. When the underground trolley was shown to be feasible, Congress passed an act reading in part as follows: "That the said Metropolitan Eailroad Company be, and the same is hereby authorized, empowered and required to equip and operate the lines of its cars upon and along * * * with an underground electric system for the propulsion of such cars." Under this order Washington was the first city in the country to secure the underground trolley. Under the reserved power to alter, amend or repeal grants at will Congress has required different companies to make arrangements for issuing transfers from the line of one company to those of another, and it has also 74 required different companies to use certain tracks in common where he public interests would be served by such an arrangement. In framing franchise legislation for Porto Eico Congress made pro- vision for this same form of indefinite term grant. In view of the fact that the indefinite term franchise has worked so well in practice, it may be in order to question the statement of the Massa- chusetts committee that found in favor of this form of grant that "such a franchise is to the last degree illogical. ' ' Things that are illogical usually do not work well, in the long run at least. The fact that the indefinite term franchise has actually produced such satisfactory results in practice must lead one to inquire if it is not really correct in principle, despite its seeming illogical character. As the Massachusetts committee very clearly and very correctly points out, the street car, in evolutionary development, is " nothing more nor less than an improved omnibus, and the tramway a special feature in the pave- ment of the public way; a feature adapted, it is true, to the car's special use, but not necessarily excluding from general use the portion of the street in which it is laid. This is all the street railway was fifty years ago, when first laid; it is all it is now an improved line of omnibuses, running over a special pavement. If this fact be firmly grasped and borne constantly in mind, the discussion, and the principles underlying it, are greatly sim- plified. The analogy throughout is with the omnibus line, and not with the railroad train; with the public thoroughfare, and not with the private right-of-way. Upon this distinction, indeed, all the questions now to be discussed, whether of taxation or of franchise privilege and obligation, will be found to turn. " Now, the omnibus is operated under a license that gives no right as against the authority granting the license that cannot be altered or taken away at any time. All would concede the unwisdom and impolicy of making the license for the omnibus a binding contract for a definite period of time that could not be altered or revoked by the granting authority, no matter how conditions might change, and no matter how arbitrary and over- bearing the manager of the omnibus line might be in his dealings with the public. And yet the indefinite term grant or revocable license for the street car, which is only an improved omnibus, is conceived to be illogical. We cannot think that it is so. On the contrary, the indefinite term grant is nearer in accord with the correct principle than is the term grant. Because of the great outlay involved in establishing a street railway system, it is said, the owners of such property ought to have some assur- ance that their property value will not be destroyed by some hasty act of revocation. And so they ought. But the assurance should be that, if their rights to use the street be revoked, their property suitable to and used for street railway purposes should be taken off their hands at a fair valuation; 75 not that they should be privileged to remain in undisputed possession of the public streets for a definite period of time, whether they serve the public well or ill. The Street Eailway Commission believes that the definite term grant, whatever its duration, is open to serious objections. It is of opinion that a grant of indefinite duration but subject to termination at any time upon cer- tain conditions, one of which should be the taking of the property of the grantee at a fair valuation, would be productive of much better results. But this idea is so much at variance with commonly accepted views in this state concerning franchise grants, and would mark such a radical departure from present policy, that the Commission has hesitated to do more than to com- mend the idea to public favor. It has not sought to incorporate the idea into the draft of the bill herewith submitted. As a modification of this idea, however, and as a means of controlling the situation in the interest of the public, the Commission would recommend that grants hereafter made contain a provision giving the city the right to terminate the grant and to take over the property at an appraised valuation at the end of every five year period. This provision should be inserted primarily with a view to its use only in case public dissatisfaction with service and conditions should be so great as to make a change in management imperative. With such a provision in the grant there is much less likelihood that there would be cause for public dissatisfaction. 76 APPENDIX B. Extracts from the Report of the Metropolitan Im- provements Commission of 1909, created to study the Boston situation. Confusion or rigidity of movement in a terminal situation will produce the same confusion and absence of flexibility throughout the entire trans- portation line using that terminal. * * * * * * * There has been no united effort or plan for raising the freight termi- nals to the modern standard of efficiency or economy. They require radical improvement if the future commercial opportunities of Boston are to be met. The water terminals are mainly owned and controlled by the railroads and other transportation lines. They are already becoming congested to the point of interfering with the despatch and economy of business, and are in no way comparable in their arrangements and facilities with those of many other cities of less commercial importance. Whether these deficiencies in terminal facilities have already retarded the commercial growth of the city is a question which may not reward discussion, but certain it is that the existing railroad and harbor terminals as now arranged and admin- istered offer slender encouragement to the legitimate aspirations for the future. Greater Boston as a Terminal District. Greater Boston being in effect one terminal district; the proper improve- ment and development of its terminal facilities should be treated as a single problem. The present arrangement of separate and independent freight terminals for the several railroads and lines of water transporta- tion should be abandoned, and in its place there should be adopted a com- prehensive plan for a flexible and efficient system of interchange terminals, whereby commodities, whether in carload or cargo bulk, or in lesser lots, may be delivered and transshipped from railroad to railroad, or from land to water, or vice versa, and distributed among consignees, with the highest attainable expedition and economy. The establishment of such a system of interchange terminals is of the greatest importance to Boston. The con- trolling features of such a system should be direct and effective connec- tion between all lines of railroad entering the city and every portion of 77 the terminal system, as well as access to and use of the system and its facilities by every railroad on equal terms for like service. Such a system necessarily involves some well-considered plan of water- terminal improvement. Boston for many years has been without any definite plan for harbor development or for the correlation and efficient connection of its terminals. With a few notable exceptions, the wharves and docks of Boston are of insufficient length to accommodate steamships of the size and type now coming into general use. The wharf sheds are mostly of wooden construction, inviting frequent conflagration. Not only should the docks be longer and wider, but the piers should be wide enough to afford ample room for streets, warehouses or freight sheds and railroad tracks. It appears very probable that between the great ports North Atlantic business will soon be done almost entirely by steamships of the combination type large passenger steamers carrying freight. Docks that are to be built should be arranged to a considerable extent for the accom- modation of passenger business as well as freight business. The very fact that so much passenger business has heretofore come to Boston, despite such inadequate facilities, demonstrates that better facilities are demanded, and that the passenger business under reasonably favorable conditions may be expected to show a large increase. It is certainly a matter of congratula- tion and encouragement that the shipping of Boston harbor has so well maintained itself with so little consideration or assistance from the public. The persistence of business under disadvantageous terminal conditions leads to the reasonable conviction that with advanced facilities the port of Boston has a promising future. But harbor terminal facilities must be furnished through private enterprise or by the commonwealth or munici- pality, or by a combination of these authorities. In view of the lack of co-operation on the part of the public authorities, the railroads are to be commended for their enterprise, not only in furnishing dock and termi- nal facilities, but in actively encouraging connecting steamship lines. With- out this the port would long since have come to a commercial standstill. The federal government has made it an invariable rule to expend noth- ing in the development of terminals or harbor facilities. It has, however, been very generous in improving the channels and waterways of the harbor, and has made large expenditures for that purpose. In addition to this, the commonwealth between 1870 and 1908 inclusive expended $4,781,435.15 in harbor improvements, represented mainly by dredging and related work. The City of Boston itself, on the other hand, has for many years done noth- ing worthy of note in developing its harbor. Added to this comparative neglect on the part of the city, many undertakings, private as well as public, have been established on the water front of the harbor which may seriously hamper and restrict its complete or ideal treatment in the future. Defective facilities and disordered conditions have been allowed to remain unrem- edied, although their injurious effect upon Boston's commerce has been repeatedly recognized and brought to the public attention. 78 The progressive ports of the world have adopted the contrary policy, and it is now becoming generally recognized that the wise administration of any port requires that it shall plan its facilities and arrangements ahead of present demands, and thus be prepared to meet whatever the immediate future may require. Less important commercially than the improvement of freight and water terminals, but of prime consequence to the welfare and safety of the people, is the early adaptation, of the railroad passenger terminals in Boston to modern requirements. The geographical position of Boston, its congested territory and the habits of its people make it the one city above all others which requires well-ordered, rapid and comfortable subur- ban transportation. The electrification of all railroad passenger lines in the Metropolitan District within the next few years is highly probable. Changes in present terminal structures and arrangements whether with reference to freight or passenger terminals should therefore be carefully studied, with due regard to that probable and far-reaching change in trac- tion methods and its inevitable effect upon terminal problems. Freight Terminals Radically Reformed. The first and most important step of progress must be a general recognition by the public that these matters are of vital interest, and that they are to be dealt with as different but essential features of the one problem of transportation as applied to a commercial and industrial center. A complete and comprehensive plan of improvement should be worked out to a finality, in order that when the plan is at length adopted there shall be no doubt of its effectiveness or feasibility. The studies of the commission have necessarily been preliminary; no detailed engineering plans or estimates of cost of suggested improvements and developments have been made. The many lines of investigation entrusted to the com mission have not left it sufficient time or money for the preparation of such plans or estimates. Final studies should be along the broadest and most intelligent lines, without restriction as to any reasonable expense. The essential thing is to have a plan that is known to be right, and then to follow it without substantial deviation as soon as conditions, financial and otherwise, permit. The main purpose is to secure an adequate ulti- mate development of terminal facilities for the transfer, delivery and distribution of freight, and the requisite improvements in the Boston passenger terminals. How to Achieve the Needed Improvements. It is % very important, nevertheless, that the public should reach some definite and comprehensive plan with reference to all these desirable railroad, terminal and harbor developments, in order that they may be 79 carried forward without unnecessary delay. To arrive at such a plan, as a completed study, will certainly require very considerable time and expense, involving engineering details and an exhaustive examination with reference to the matter of cost. The commission recommends that the work of formulating such a plan for ultimate presentation to the legisla- ture be placed in charge of a commission to be appointed by the Governor -and Council, with no other duty than the working out of this great trans- portation problem, and that no reasonable expense be spared to have the studies of that commission so final and complete as to deserve and secure the fullest public approval. When, at length, after the final report of such commission, the time shall have arrived for definite action in that regard, the equipment of Boston with a proper system of freight and water terminals, with modern warehouses and port facilities, as well as the reformation of its pas- senger terminals, should be worked out and completed under public direc- tion. There is probably no practicable alternative. Assuming that such improvements could be carried out by a company projected purely as a private enterprise, the transfer and switching charges which a modern terminal system is designated to eliminate would necessarily be continued by such a company as its only source of revenue, and might thereby become perpetuated. The exaction of such charges from the railroads would inevitably evoke their lasting opposition. On the other hand, in so far-reaching a matter, action by the railroads themselves on their own initiative, or effective co-operation among them, is extremely unlikely. This is especially true when there are so many companies owning or oper- ating railroads entering the city. Public direction with railroad co-opera- tion offers the most promising solution of the problem. But such a plan should be,, and if it is to succeed must be, made reasonably attractive to the railroads. No effort should be spared to secure their full co-operation with the public on equitable terms. It is eminently fit that so compre- hensive a proposition as that of terminal and harbor development should be carried out by the united action of the public authorities and the railroads. They would enjoy in common the benefits of an increasing , commerce and business, with the resulting growth in population and in wealth. They should, therefore, participate in bringing these things to . pass. Bearing this view of the matter in mind, the most feasible method of bringing the present inadequate and ill-connected terminals of Boston intq. one great modern terminal system would appear to be through a terminal company, to be organized and promoted by the joint action of the public authorities and all the railroad companies. The reconstruction of the passenger terminals and their connection by the proposed tunnel, upon the adoption of the above or any similar plan, should be carried ' out chrough the instrumentality of the same terminal company. Such 80 terminal company should acquire the terminal properties and sites" for terminals now owned by the railroads, with all connecting track lines, so far as they would form an essential or natural part of the proposed termi- nal system. Whatever plan may be adopted for acquiring and paying for these properties, its one paramount requisite is that it shall be perfectly just to railroads and public alike. If a basis of acquisition could be formulated agreeable to the railroads, payment for the properties acquired from them might be made in stock or bonds of the terminal company, or partly in each class of securities. All or a portion of the bonds of the terminal company, as the case might be, could be issued for additional terminal properties and for improvements, construction and developments. To secure the advantage of lower interest rates, and in recognition of its own par- ticipation in the whole proceeding, the Commonwealth might very prop- erly guarantee the payment of the bonds of the terminal company, the mortgage securing such bonds to contain proper sinking-fund requirements. Following various precedents, the bonds might with equal propriety be exempted from taxation and made a savings-bank investment. The man- agement of the terminal company should be by the railroads and the Com- monwealth jointly, each electing a definite proportion of its board of directors. Terminal operations would thus be controlled and managed in a way that would amply conserve railroad interests and at the same time afford a proper measure of protection to the public. With appropriate legislation there would be 110 legal obstacle in the way of such joint action by the public authorities and the railroads. Moreover, there ought to be no reason why this should not be entirely practicable. ******* The commission has sought to make it clear that the water front of the Metropolitan District affords the highest possible opportunity and promise for commercial and industrial development. It follows as a corol- lary that the source of such opportunities should be in every way properly safe-guarded. Nothing further should be done by the public in the way of takings for purposes or otherwise which will divert any portion of this great water front from its potential use for commerce and industry. The commission has recommended the permanent reservation of certain areas within Boston harbor for the location of a future system of docks. It is a matter of regret that the most available industrial sites along the water front cannot be similarly reserved. SI SYRACUSE, - N.Y. PAT. JAN. 21, I8O8 351781 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFOENIA LIBEAEY BERKELEY THIS BOOK IS DUE ON THE LAST DATE STAMPED BELOW Books not returned on time are subject to a fine of 50c per volume after the third day overdue, increasing to $1.00 per volume after the sixth day. Books not in demand may be renewed if application is made before expiration of loan period. MAY 5 1917