GIFT OF GIFT FFH 25 1913 CONSTRUCTION CONSTITUTIONALITY LONG AND SHORT HAUL CLAUSE INTERSTATE COMMERCE ACT AS AMENDED JUNE 18, 1910 n J A. PAPER Br AI.FRED P. THOM Gbitbhai. CoiTirsBt at Washington- of Southkrn RAII.WAX OOMPANT 0\O Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2007 with funding from Microsoft Corporation http://www.archive.oVg/details/constructionconsOOthomrich CONSTRUCTION CONSTITUTIONALITY LONG AND SHORT HAUL CLAUSE INTERSTATE COMMERCE ACT AS AMENDED JUNE 18, 1910 A PAPER BF AI.FREI3 P. THOM GsirBKAX. COTTSrSErr ax WASHIN-OTOIT of SOXTTHSRir RAIIiVTAY Compawx 'TV -A g.4^' w IS SECTION 4 OF THE ACT TO REGULATE COMMERCE, AS AMENDED JUNE 18, 1910, CONSTITUTIONAL IN SO FAR AS IT UNDER- TAKES TO PROHIBIT A SMALLER CHARGE FOR THE TRANSPORTATION OF PASSEN- GERS, OR OF LIKE KIND OF PROPERTY, FOR A LONGER THAN FOR A SHORTER DISTANCE OVER THE SAME LINE OR ROUTE IN THE SAME DIRECTION UNDER THE CONDITIONS AND WITH THE QUALIFICATIONS STATED IN THE ACT? In order to determine this question it is necessary to arrive at the proper interpretation of the section as it now stands. So far as pertinent to the inquiry, the language of the statute is as follows : **That it shall be unlawful for any common carrier subject to the provisions of this Act to charge or receive any greater compensation in the aggregate for the transportation of passen- gers, or of like kind of property, for a shorter than for a longer distance over the same line or route in the same direction, the shorter being in- cluded within the longer distance. * * * Pro- vided, however, that upon application to the Interstate Commerce Commission such common carrier may in special cases, after investigation, (3) 257194 be authorized by the Commission to charge less for longer than for shorter distances for the transportation of passengers or property, and the Conmiission may from time to time pre- scribe the extent to which such designated com- mon carrier may be relieved from the operation of this section." The proviso to the above section is practically the same as the proviso contained in section 4 of the Act to Eegulate Commerce before it was amended on June 18, 1910. The first part of the section was, however, before the amendment of June 18, 1910, as follows: **That it shall be unlawful for any common carrier subject to the provisions of this act to charge or receive any greater compensation in the aggregate for the transportation of passen- gers, or of like kind of property, under substan- tially similar circumstances and conditions, for a shorter than for a longer distance over the same line in the same direction, the shorter being included within the longer distance/' It will, therefore, be seen that, considered from the standpoint of the question now under discussion, the important amendment introduced by the act of June 18, 1910, was to omit from the section, as it previously was, the words ^^ under substantially similar circum- stances and conditions.'' The question for determination, therefore, is, what is the effect of the omission of these words upon the interpretation of the statute? In order to ascertain this, it would be well to revert to the established interpretation of this section of the act as it stood before the amendment in question. In respect to this it is to be noted that at no time has it been the intention of Congress to make an inflexible rule that there should be no smaller charge for a longer distance in cases covered by the statute. When the Act to Regulate Commerce, finally adopted in 1887, was before Congress for consideration, the House, under the leadership of Mr. Eeagan, of Texas, adopted an inflexible rule on this subject forbidding absolutely the greater charge for the shorter haul, while the Senate adopted the view that the rule should be subject to exceptions when the circumstances and conditions required it. These divergent views between the House and Senate were sent to a conference committee, and as a result of such conference the sec- tion, as it stood prior to the amendment of June 18, 1910, was adopted by both houses of Congress and became the law — the law thus providing that the rule should not be inflexible, but should be subject to the exceptions required by any substantial dissimilarity of circumstances and conditions. Again, when the amendment to the 4th section was under consideration by Congress in 1910, Mr. Hardy, of Texas, proposed an amendment, the effect of which was to strike out all provisos and make an inflexible rule forbidding absolutely the greater charge for the shorter haul. His views on this subject were thus expressed by him on page 5917 of the Congressional Eecord : **Now, Mr. Chairman, to state briefly the pur- poses of the amendment offered by me, it means simply to leave the unconditional proviso that no road should ever be allowed to charge more for the short haul than the long haul covering the same space or portion of the railway. ' ' It thus appears that, on both occasions when this section was under consideration by Congress, the prop- osition was presented, debated, and rejected that there should be a hard and fast rule on this subject. In view of this and of the debates in Congress on the subject, we think it may be fairly stated that the exception was considered by Congress as necessary to meet a sub- stantial condition, and that without it the rule would never have been enacted. As soon as the act of 1887 was passed, important questions arose as to its interpretation. In re- spect to these questions, elaborate hearings were had and most mature consideration given by the Interstate Commerce Commission. Two views of the meaning of the act were presented, one view being that no ex- ception from the general rule was lawful unless made with the previous sanction of the Commission, and the other that no order of relief from the Commission was required when the circumstances and conditions were substantially dissimilar ; since the carrier, in act- ing in accordance with them, would commit no breach of the law, although it would be responsible in case it should afterwards be found that the circumstances and conditions were misconceived or misjudged. On this question the Commission, as then consti- tuted, was unanimous, and Judge Cooley, delivering its opinion, held: **We have listened, with an earnest desire to reach a just conclusion, to all the arguments presented on the construction of the statute, by those appearing either to advocate or to oppose the applications, and after mature consideration we are satisfied that the statute does not require that the Commission shall prescribe in every instance the exceptional ca^e and grant its order for relief before the carrier is at liberty in its tariffs to depart from the general rule. The terms of the statute clearly lead to the opposite conclusion. It declares : '* *It shall be unlawful for any common car- rier subject to the provisions of this act to charge or receive any greater compensation in the aggregate for the transportation of passen- gers or of the like kind of property under sub- stantially similar circumstances and conditions for a shorter than for a longer distance over the same line in the same direction, the shorter being included in the longer distance.' **Here we have clearly stated what is unlaw- ful and forbidden, and for doing the unlawful and forbidden act penalties are then provided. But that which the act does not declare unlawful 8 must remain lawful if it was so before, and that which it fails to forbid the carrier is left at lib- erty to do without permission from any one. The charging or receiving the greater compen- sation for the shorter than for the longer haul is seen to be forbidden only when both are under substantially similar circumstances and conditions, and, therefore, if in any case the carrier, without first obtaining an order of re- lief, shall depart from the general rule, its doing so will not alone convict it of illegality, since if the circumstances and conditions of the two hauls are dissimilar the statute is not violated/' This view was sustained by the Supreme Court of the United States in Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Alabama Midland Ey., 168 U. S., 168. Under the law, therefore, as it was prior to the amendment of 1910, the carrier possessed the right, without any previous action of the Commission, to charge less for a longer than for a shorter haul, if the circumstances and conditions of the two hauls were substantially dissimilar. The result of this, of course, was that the 4th sec- tion, as it then stood, afforded no relief for those who complained of the smaller charge for the longer dis- tance unless the complaining party should file a peti- tion before the Interstate Commerce Commission, and should obtain an order affirmatively declaring that the circumstances and conditions of the longer haul were not substantially dissimilar from those of the shorter haul. When Congress came to the consideration of amend- ments to this section, in 1910, it had become convinced, justly or unjustly, that the carrier, availing itself of the power of initiation just mentioned, was practically administering all prohibitions as to the smaller charge for the longer distance out of the law. It had become convinced that this was a great evil, and listened with approval to the protest that was made against this power by a considerable portion of the public. It had come to believe that the courts had given such a con- struction to the section as, in the language of Mr. Mann, ^^to destroy its life.'' It was thought that the general rule on this subject had been wiped out of existence by the initiative of the carriers. We do not think, however, that by the omission of the words ^' under similar circumstances and condi- tions,'' it was the intention of the act to change the principles of the law which had governed the making of rates. The Act to Eegulate Commerce still provides in its first section that — "all charges made for any service rendered or to be rendered in the transportation of passen- gers or property shall be just and reasonable;" in its second section that ''no carrier shall collect or receive from any person or persons a greater or less compensa- 10 tion for any service rendered, or to be rendered, in the transportation of passengers or property, than it collects or receives from any other per- son or persons for doing for him or them a like and contemporaneous service in the transporta- tion of a like kind of traffic under similar cir- cumstances and conditions,^' and, in section three, that it shall be unlawful for any common carrier, subject to the provisions of the act, '*to make or give any undue or unreasonable preference or advantage to any particular per- son, etc., or locality, or any particular descrip- tion of traffic in any respect whatever.'' These provisions of the Act to Eegulate Commerce express its substantial and dominating purposes and are to be read into, and to be considered a qualifica- tion of, every other provision of the act. This, in ef- fect, was stated, in respect to the requirement of the first section, by Mr. Mann in the debate in the House of Representatives on this subject. At page 4796 of the Congressional Record, in dis- cussing the question as to whether the discretion cre- ated by the proviso of the act was a limited or un- limited discretion, and, therefore, whether or not it was a delegation of legislative power, he says : '^Remember, whatever the Commission does in respect to this matter, it is always bound by the act of Congress that rates shall be just and reasonable and that railroad companies shall 11 not establish unjust and unreasonable rates ; so that practically what we do here is to give the Commission power to say what in a particular case shall be a just and reasonable rate, al- though we declare as a general proposition that it shall be unjust and unreasonable to charge a higher rate for a short haul than for a long haul/' He further stated, when this bill was introduced in the House, and he was making his explanation in re- spect to it, that there were serious conditions of com- petition which the law must not undertake absolutely to forbid. Thus, on page 4795 of the Congressional Eecord, he says: ^^The intention of the act (the original act) was undoubtedly to provide that in general, as an ordinary proposition, a railroad company could not charge less between two points than it charged between one of those points and a point midway, or part way, between the original two points. In other words, they should not be al- lowed to run freight from point A through point B to point C, and charge less between A and C than they charge between A and B. And yet water competition seems to prevent a hard and fast rule on that subject, because railroads are necessarily in competition not only with regular passenger and freight steamers, but also with tramp ships on the ocean and on the lakes and rivers, and must compete with these vessels. And it may often happen that the railroad com- pany under the principles which underlie the 12 making of freight rates cannot afford to make its rate lower than it does between points A and B, and yet can afford to make some profit out of carrying freight at a lower rate between points A and C. That theory controlled Con- gress when it enacted the original act, and I think no one has ever contended that there may not be cases where, under proper management of railroads, a less charge may be made for a long haul than for a short haul.'' Again : ^^The Commission may say what is a reason- able rate to different points ; but if, in order to get some of the business which otherwise would all go by water, the railroad company wants to carry freight at less than is a reasonable rate on all its business, nobody would wish to pre- vent it doing that, because to that extent you could lower the rates.'' And again, on page 4797, in answer to the question: ^ ^ Is it practicable to legislate so as to deprive New York and San Francisco of the benefit of the ocean, that no injustice may be done to the towns inland?" Mr. Mann said: **I think not. I think that San Francisco and New York and other ports on the ocean have a natural advantage which cannot, and ought not if it could, be taken away from them. In other words, when you come to the question of fixing freight rates, please remember these proposi- tions: A railroad company must pay its oper- 13 ating expenses. It must pay the cost of main- tenance. It must pay the cost of its general offices. It must pay the interest on its bonds. It must pay, if it is successful, dividends on its stock. It must carry some freight at profit enough to make dividends on the stock. ^^It may carry some freight which will help it to pay interest on its bonds, and it may be met by a situation where it can carry a large amount of freight at rates which will more than pay the operating expenses or a proportionate share of the operating expenses, which will more than pay its proportionate share of the cost of main- tenance, which will more than pay its share of the cost of the general offices, which will con- tribute something to the interest on the bonds, but which will not contribute anything towards dividends on the stock or which will not even contribute enough towards the interest on the bonds to pay more than 1 or 2 per cent, whereas the rate would be 4 or 5 per cent. Now, with that large amount of freight which it may get if it competes successfully with other methods of transportation, it is the duty of the railroad company to secure that freight at lower terms than are practicable to pay interest and divi- dends if it carried all freight on the same basis, and that will be true forever in railroads in com- petition between New York and San Francisco, competing with ocean methods of transporta- tion, and ought to be so. It is true through many parts of the United States, and ought to be so, because in the end it tends to reduce the rates on freight throughout the country. 14 *'0f course, under existing law, as construed by the courts, the long and short-haul clause amounts to nothing. Under the proposition which we have presented, if enacted into law, there must be application made in special cases to the Commission which grants authority to charge a less amount for the longer distance than for the shorter distance, and we think the power can safely be lodged in the hands of the Commission. It is perfectly patent it must be lodged somewhere. We will never reach a basis in this country, and ought not, with our im- mense railroad mileage and with our great water carriage, with our long lines of road, where we charge railroad rates on the mileage basis or where we put all classes upon the same basis.'' It will thus be seen that there are conditions of competition well recognized by the promoters of this legislation as conditions which the law must not under- take absolutely to ignore or forbid. Most of these illustrations, as given on the floor of the House, were of water competition, but they were not confined to water competition. One of the notable cases, having no reference to water competition, is that of the com- petition of commodities between the citrus fruits of California and the citrus fruits of Florida in the com- peting markets of the country, and throughout the de- bate it was recognized that the economic rule which justifies the smaller charge for the longer haul was not at stake, but that the administration of the law 15 which, in the judgment of Congress, was faulty, was at stake and must be corrected. If, therefore, as stated by Mr. Mann on the floor of the House, and as seems to be certainly true, the provision of the first section of the act, requiring all charges made for any service rendered in the trans- portation of passengers and property to be just and reasonable, must be taken as a qualification of section 4, and must, therefore, qualify the power of the In- terstate Commerce Commission under the proviso to permit or forbid a smaller charge for the longer distance, then it will be necessary for the Com- mission, in passing on applications for this re- lief, to determine whether, under the circum- stances and conditions of the longer and of the shorter haul, the charging of a smaller rate for the longer distance is just and reasonable. In other words, in passing on such applications, it will be necessary for the Commission to determine whether the traffic moves to the longer distance and to the shorter distance, ^^ under substantially similar circum- stances and conditions.*' Under the law as it was before the amendment, the carrier was entitled to the initiative in determining this question, but its determination might upon appli- cation to the Commission be overruled. Under the law as changed, the carrier cannot take the initiative in respect to it, but the question must in the first in- stance be determined by the Commission. The ques- 16 tion, however, to be determined in both cases is the same; only the method of determination is altered by the amendment. This is in line with the policy of Congress in respect to another important matter embraced in the same amendatory act of June 18, 1910. Prior to that act,^ the carriers could, in all instances, increase their rates without the previous consent of the Commission. The initiative as to increases of rates was, prior to the amendment, completely in the carrier. By the amend- ment, the Commission was given the discretionary power to deprive the carrier of its rights to initially increase rates and was authorized to inaugurate an investigation, either upon complaint or upon its own motion, for the purpose of determining upon the pro- priety of proposed increases. The only difference be- tween this last-mentioned case and the case of the long and short-haul clause, is that the carrier is de- prived in a qualified way of its power of initiation in respect to increase of rates, while it is deprived abso- lutely of its power of initiation in respect to the long and short-haul charge; and the Commission is clothed with a discretionary power to assume the initiative in respect to an increase of rates, while it is made its absolute duty, on the application of the carrier, to as- sume the initiative in relation to the long and short- haul charge. In this view of the amendment, the statute would confer upon the Commission a power, in respect to 17 fixing rates for the longer haul, measured by the rule that the rates so fixed shall be just and reasonable under the circumstances and conditions of the longer haul as compared with the circumstances and con- ditions of the shorter haul, and not an unqualified, un- controlled, and unmeasured discretion. It is believed that this is the proper construction of the act. As thus construed, it is believed to be con- stitutional, notwithstanding the fact that it deprives the carrier of the initiative as to these rates. If the Com- mission should decide arbitrarily against the applica- tion of the carrier for relief, in a case where there existed, as a fact, such substantial dissimilarity of circumstances and conditions as to make the smaller charge for the longer haul just and reasonable, or if the Commission should determine that question er- roneously, it is believed that the carrier would have relief in the courts to the same extent that it would have if there was, in a proper case, an arbitrary or erroneous determination by the Commission against the right of the carrier to increase its rates. In stating the proposition that, as thus construed, the fourth section is constitutional, we have not over- looked the contention, very intelligently made, that the requirement of the act that all rates shall be just and reasonable, is not a sufficient primary standard to prevent the power conferred upon the Commission in this regard from being a delegation of legislative authority, and the further contention that, irrespective 2— E 18 of the sufficiency of the primary standard, the power involves the delegation of legislative power because the Commission's authority cannot be exercised ex- cept upon application of the carrier. In respect to the contention that the primary stand- ard prescribed by the act is not sufficiently definite, it would seem only necessary to refer to the following cases : Field vs. Clark, 143 U. S., 649 ; Buttfield vs. Stranahan, 192 U. S., 470; Union Bridge Co. vs. United States, 204 U. S., 364; United States vs. Heinszen, 206 U. S., 370; St. Louis & Iron Mountain Ry. Co. vs. Taylor, 210U. S., 281; Monongahela Bridge Co. vs. United States, 216 U. S., 177. In these cases enough is stated, in: respect to the primary standard, to show conclusively, in my judg- ment, that the Supreme Court will hold that a require- ment that a rate to be authorized by the Commission shall be just and reasonable, is a sufficient primary standard and that an exercise of power by the Com- mission, under such authority, will not amount to the exercise of legislative power. In respect to the contention that, irrespective of the sufficiency of the primary standard, the power of the Commission cannot be exercised except upon the ini- 19 tiative' of the carrier in making the application, it is not believed that in the present trend of popular and judicial thought a proposition of this kind, no matter how technically meritorious, will be approved by the Supreme Court. In fact, if the primary standard of determination by the Commission is sufficient, that would seem to end the question of whether or not the delegation of power is legislative; for, if the delega- tion of power in itself is not the delegation of a legislative power, it could hardly be made so by the method of its exercise. It would seem more pertinent to inquire, in this connection, whether the operation of the law would be equal and uniform, but, as above stated, it is not believed that any constitutional objec- tion would, under current conditions, be upheld. The same relief and the same equality of protection under the law would be open to all alike. That the foregoing interpretation of this amend- ment is proper, is strengthened by the consideration that any other construction would render the act un- constitutional. As said by Mr. Justice White, in delivering the opin- ion of the court in United States vs. Delaware "& Hud- son Company, 213 U. S., 366, 407-8 : ^*It is elementary when the constitutionality of a statute is assailed, if the statute be reason- ably susceptible of two interpretations, by one of which it would be unconstitutional and by the other valid, it is our plain duty to adopt that construction which will save the statute 20 from constitutional infirmity. Knights Tem- plars Indemnity Co. vs, Jarman, 187 U. S., 197, 205. And unless this rule be considered as meaning that our duty is to first decide that a statute is unconstitutional and then proceed to hold that such ruling was unnecessary because the statute is susceptible of a meaning, which causes it not to be repugnant to the Constitu- tion, the rule plainly must mean that where a statute is susceptible of two constructions, by one of which grave and doubtful constitutional questions arise and by the other of which such questions are avoided, our duty is to adopt the latter, Harriman vs. Interstate Com. Com., 211 U. S., 407.'^ Before proceeding, to discuss the question whether, assuming that the above construction is unsound, the clause is valid, it may be well to state certain prin- ciples which have been established by the courts as to what are circumstances and conditions which make a lower charge for the longer distance just and reason- able. From a reference to the adjudicated cases it will be seen that all the substantial facts surrounding a serv- ice must be considered in determining whether a charge for it is just and reasonable. In the cases thus far presented, the question of whether or not a lower charge for a longer than for a shorter distance is just and reasonable, has always arisen under a statute which in terms permitted a lower charge for the longer than for the shorter distance if the circumstances and conditions of the service were substantially dissimilar ; 21 but it is held, as in Louisville & Nashville Railroad Company vs. Behlmer, 175 U. S., 674, that the deter- mination of the question whether in any ease substan- tial dissimilarity of circumstances and conditions ex- ists, must be made subject to **the absolute command of the statute that all rates shall be just and reason- able.^' The decisions, therefore, which hold that all the ma- terial facts surrounding the service, including the ex- istence of substantial competition, whether from water carriers or other sources, must be considered, are, in effect, decisions establishing the principle that a rate made lower for a longer than for a shorter haul by substantial competition, is, to the extent that it is in- fluenced by such competition, just and reasonable. Cincinnati, New Orleans & Texas Pacific Ry. vs. Interstate Commerce Conunission, 162 U. S., 184; Texas & Pacific Ry. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 197 ; Interstate Commerce Commission vs, Alabama Midland Ry., 168 U. S., 144; Louisville & Nashville R. R. vs. Behlmer, 175 U. S., 648; East Tennessee, Virginia & Georgia Ry. vs, In^ terstate Commerce Commission, 181 U. S., 1; Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Louisville & Nashville R. R., 190 U. S., 273; Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Chicago Great Western Ry., 209 U. S., 108. 22 IF THE FOREGOINa INSTRUCTION IS NOT SOUND, IS THE PROVISION OF THE ACT AS IT NOW STANDS CONSTITUTIONAL? In addition to the interpretation above given of the amendment of June 18, 1910, one other construction may be suggested. This construction is that the pro- viso by which authority is conferred upon the Com- mission to permit the making of a smaller charge for a longer than a shorter haul, amounts to an absolute discretion in the Commission, unlimited by any rule laid down by Congress, and subject to no supervision. It is believed that any such construction of the amend- ment would make it unconstitutional. It would be either a delegation by Congress to the Commission of power to make rates without providing any rule to be admin- istered by it, or it would be a delegation by Congress to the Commission of authority, in its unlimited, un- qualified, and unregulated discretion, to suspend a legislative act of Congress. To do one or the other would involve the exercise of a legislative power by the Commission. The making of rates is essentially a legislative act. Prentis vs. Atlantic Coast Line R. R., 211 U. S., 226. The suspension of a law of Congress at the absolute discretion of the officer entrusted with the power, and 23 not made to depend upon the finding by him of a cer- tain fact, is also the exercise of a legislative power. Field vs. Clark, 143 U. S., 693. The principle which forbids the delegation by Con- gress of any part of its legislative power is thus an- nounced by Mr. Justice Lamar: * * That no part of its legislative power can be delegated by Congress to any other department of the Government, executive or judicial, is an axiom in constitutional law, and is universally recognized as a principle essential to the integ- rity and maintenance of the system of govern- ment ordained by the Constitution.'' The same principle is, in the case of Field vs. Clark, thus announced by Mr. Justice Harlan, who delivered the opinion of the majority of the court : **That Congress cannot delegate legislative power to the President is a principle universally recognized as vital to the integrity and mainte- nance of the system of government ordained by the Constitution.'' Of course, the same principle applies to any other delegation of legislative power. The delegation of power by Congress to suspend one of its acts is, when justified at all, universally jus- tified on the ground that the effect of the act is to direct the exercise of the power of suspension upon the ascertainment, by the person to whom the power is delegated, of the existence of a particular fact or state of conditions or circumstances. Union Bridge Co. vs. 24 U. S., 204 U. S., 382. If, therefore, in this case. Con- gress has established a rule that the rates which the Commission may authorize shall be just and reason- able under the circumstances of the carriage, then the delegation of power to the Commission to first ascer- tain that fact and afterwards to authorize a rate in accordance with it, is, as heretofore stated, believed to be a valid delegation of power ; but if the limitation that rates shall be just and reasonable under the cir- cumstances of the service does not apply to this sec- tion, and if Congress has thus fixed no rule for the government of the Commission in this regard, but simply means to delegate its 'legislative discretion to the Commission without determining the standard of its exercise, it is a delegation of legislative power and is unconstitutional. Moreover, if the power expressed in this proviso to section 4 is purely arbitrary and is controlled by no regulation or restraint, it is unconstitutional for that reason alone. The very idea that one man may be compelled to hold his property, or any material right essential to its enjoyment, at the mere will or caprice of another, is intolerable in any country where free- dom prevails, and is contrary to the Constitution. Yick Wo vs. Hopkins, 118 U. S., 356; City of Baltimore vs, Kadecke, 49 Md., 217 ; Ex parte Sing Lee, 96 Cal., 354; City of Sioux Falls vs. Kirby, 6 S. D., 62; City of Eichmond vs. Dudley, 129 Ind., 112; State vs. Mahner, 43 La., 496. 25 This last-stated proposition is, however, denied, in respect to the immediate question before us, by the Su- preme Court of the United States in Louisville & Nashville R. R. ^5. Kentucky, 183 U. S., 503 ; but, for reasons hereinafter stated, it is hoped that this case will not be adhered to by the Supreme Court when the question is presented for further consideration. In the event that the delegation of power contained in the proviso to the 4th section is unconstitutional, it becomes proper to consider whether the effect of that unconstitutionality is to render invalid the whole of the 4th section, or only the proviso, leaving an in- flexible rule forbidding the charging of a smaller rate for the longer distance. This question will now be con- sidered. IS THE SECTION SEPARABLE, AND WILL THE PROVISO ONLY BE DECLARED INVALID? It is not believed that the court would hold that the proviso of the section is separable from the other por- tion of it. As has been hereinbefore noted, Congress, when enacting the original law in 1887, and also in adopting the amendment in 1910, was confronted with the proposition to enact an absolute, inflexible rule on the subject. On both occasions it refused, and delib- erately refused, to do so. It can, therefore, in the light of this legislative history, hardly be claimed that Con- gress would have adopted an absolute rule without 26 condition, and, if not, the two parts of the statute can- not be considered separable. Moreover, when the reasons are examined which caused Congress to decline to enact an absolute and in- flexible rule, it will be found that they are so potential as to prevent a court from concluding that the two pro- visions of the statute are separable. It is shown in Judge Cooley^s opinion, hereinbefore referred to, that the commerce of the country could not be conducted under an inflexible rule. Thus it was said by Judge Cooley : ^^It was fairly shown before us, that instances exist, and may be found, along the route of pe- titioner's lines in the States of Kentucky, Ten- nessee, Georgia, Alabama, Mississippi, and Lou- isiana, where the competition of water-ways forces down the railroad rates below what it is possible to make them at noncompetitive points and still maintain the roads with success or ejSiciency. The reason is that the carriers by water can perform the service at very much less cost than the carriers by land. The general fact is that railroad rates for the transportation of property ""must approximate closely those which are made between the same points by steamer, and the steamer rates are generally, if not invariably, much below what the railroads can afford to accept upon all their business. In such cases, if competition is maintained, more must be charged at interior points than can be obtained at the points of competition; and if the competitive rates are such as are productive of some gain, however slight, the non-competi- 27 tive points are likely to receive indirect advan- tage therefrom, while the competitive points have the larger and more direct benefit, and are afforded a choice of agencies in transportation whose rivalry may fairly be expected to keep the cost down to a minimum. The interior points may have no ground for complaint in such a case, provided the rates they are charged are in themselves just and reasonable, even though the fact be that in some cases more is charged for the short than for the long haul over the same line in the same direction. This general fact is recognized the world over; and of Eng- lish railways it has been often remarked that some of them would be deprived of much of their value if they were not allowed to meet water competition by such concessions at the points of contact as the competition would compel. ^*Low rates are a necessity of the situation; and if railroads compete with water transporta- tion either on the ocean or the navigable rivers, they have no choice but to accept such rates. To compel the roads to observe strictly the gen- eral rule laid down by the fourth section would necessitate their abandonment of some classes of business in which their competition with water transportation is now of public impor- tance. ' ' I Annual Eep. I. C. C, p. 75. , This same view was extended to embrace all classes, whether from water carriers or otherwise, of substan- tial competition, by the decisions of the Supreme 28 Court of the United States in the following series of cases : Cincinnati, New Orleans & Texas Pacific By. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 184; Texas & Pacific By. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 197; Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Alabama Midland B. B., 168 U. S., 144; Louisville & Nashville B. B. vs, Behlmer, 175 U. S., 648; East Tennessee, Virginia & Georgia B. B. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 181 U. S., 1; Interstate Commerce Commission vsi Louisville & Nashville B. B., 190 U. S., 273; Interstate Commerce Commission vs, Chicago Great Western By., 209 U. S., 108. It will thus be seen that the economic law, which con- trols the movement of trafl&c under the dissimilar cir- cumstances and conditions produced by controlling forces in respect to the longer as compared to the shorter haul, is so well recognized and is so potential that it is not believed that the Supreme Court will hold that the proviso in section 4 is separable from the remainder of the statute. Of course, if the court should hold that the two por- tions of the statute are inseparable, then, if the pro- viso is unconstitutional, the whole section will fall. 29 If, however, the court should, contrary to this view, hold the two portions of the section separable, and should further hold that the proviso is unconstitutional in that it is an attempt by Congress to confer upon a commission a portion of its legislative power, or in that it is the delegation of an arbitrary, irresponsible, and tyrannical power, then the result would be that the rule forbidding a lower charge for the longer than for the shorter haul, would be absolute and inflexible, and this brings me to the consideration of the question whether an absolute and inflexible rule on this sub- ject would be constitutional. AN ABSOLUTE AND INFLEXIBLE RULE UNCONSTITUTIONAL. We are met at the outset, in considering this prop- osition, by the case of Louisville & Nashville R. R. Co. vs, Kentucky, 183 U. S., 503. If that case was rightly decided, or is upon reconsideration adhered to, and is held to be applicable to the act of Congress now under examination, it will, of course, be an end of the con- troversy. It should be noted, however, that the opinion in that case is most unsatisfactory and seems to assert propo- sitions of constitutional law which are clearly inde- fensible. In its opinion the court seems to consider that the fact that the rule in respect to the long and short haul 30 clause is contained in the constitution of the State, has some bearing upon the question to be determined. It says : ^*But, apart from such contentions (the con- tentions referred to being contentions growing out of the contract clause and the commerce clause), and looking only at the case of a com- pany voluntarily formed to carry on business wholly within a State, we are unable to see how such a company can successfully contend that it can be exempted by the courts from the opera- tion of the constitution of the State.'' The Louisville & Nashville Eailroad Company had been chartered and had been constructed long before the constitution of the State of Kentucky then being considered was adopted, and, therefore, there was no question in the case of the railroad company holding its property rights subject to rules in respect thereto established by a constitution in force at the time of and before they were acquired. It would seem, therefore, that the proposition of the court just stated would have no relevancy to the question under consideration, unless it were proposed to assert that a property right of a corporation organ- ized under the laws of a State may be violated by its constitutional provisions thereafter enacted, and yet such a proposition is so clearly opposed to all the de- cisions of the Supreme Court itself, which uniformly hold that a State cannot violate the 14th Amendment to the Federal Constitution by its own constitution any 31 more than it can by its statutes, or by any other agency of the State, that it seems impossible to suppose that any view of this sort was in the mind of the court. Eailroad Company vs, McClure, 10 Wall., 511, 515; Gunn vs. Barry, 15 Wall., 610, 623. New Orleans Gas Co. vs, Louisiana Light Co., 115 U. S., 650, 672; Bier vs. McGehee, 148 U. S., 137, 140. That the court was, in its opinion, however, laying some especial stress upon the fact that the provision in question was contained in the State's constitution is emphasized by the following quotation from the court's opinion: **When citizens of Kentucky voluntarily seek and obtain a grant from the State of a charter that it takes, holds, and operates its right sub- ject to the constitutional inhibition we are con- sidering, and are without power to challenge its validity. ' ' It seems impossible to suppose that the court in- tended by this expression to question the right of a railroad company to challenge the validity of the pro- vision of the State constitution referred to, or any other provision of that constitution, if the effect of the challenged provision was to deprive it of its property without due process of law, or to deny to it the equal protection of the laws contrary to the fourteenth 32 Amendment to the Federal Constitution, and yet why should this reference to the State constitution be made unless it, in the mind of the court, had some efficacy differentiating it from other forms of State action, in relation to the question of whether or not a property right of the railroad company was violated. Does it not seem that the court in making this decision was acting on the theory that the constitution of Kentucky, enacted after the Louisville and Nashville Railroad Company had acquired its property, qualified in some way that company's rights in its property and to some extent deprived the company of its right to the use and enjoyment of its property? While this would seem to be the necessary conse- quence of the emphasis laid upon the constitution of the State in the opinion of the court, still the court seems to go on to consider, in a way, whether the right to charge less for a longer than for a shorter haul is a property right protected by the Federal Constitution, but, in determining that question, it gives no reason except that the company holds its property subject to the constitution of the State. It says : **What we now say is, that a State corpora- tion, voluntarily formed, cannot exempt itself from the control reserved to itself by the State by its constitution, and that the plaintiff in error, if not protected by a valid contract, can- not successfully invoke the interposition of the Federal courts, in respect to the long and short- haul clause in the State constitution, on the ground simply that the railroad is property. ' ' 33 It would thus seem that the fundamental questions which should have controlled this question were not considered, or certainly were not dealt with in the opinion of the court. Moreover, it should be noted that the reason given by the court in its decision seems to refer the power exercised by the State to the power impliedly reserved in its constitution to deal with cor- porations organized under its laws. If this be the only reason on which the court acted, it may well be questioned whether the doctrine of that case will ex- tend to an act of Congress exercised in respect to a corporation organized under the laws of a State. How- ever this may be, it seems to me that the decision of the case is manifestly erroneous and withdraws some of the most substantial and valuable property rights, which a railroad company has, from the protection of the Constitution of the United States. It seems fair to hope that a case so little considered and so inadequately reasoned as the one now under discussion will not, upon further consideration, be ad- hered to by the Supreme Court of the United States, and will take rank, as an abandoned precedent, with the case of Munn vs, Illinois, 94 U. S., 113, which was, in effect, overruled by the Supreme Court in Wabash E. E. vs, Illinois, 118 U. S., 557, and other cases. Moreover, it must be remembered that the system of governmental regulation has been greatly developed and advanced since 1902, when this case was decided. Legislation on the subject has step by step been pressed 3— E 34 further and further, until it has assumed an impor- tance at this day hardly realized or appreciated ten years ago. In this view of the larger place which governmental regulation has assumed as a matter of fact in our governmental institutions, it would seem proper that principles announced in the early stages of governmental regulation should, in view of their importance and of their far-reaching consequences, be now reviewed by the courts, unembarrassed by precedents which were established at a time when com- paratively little attention had been paid to this subject and its underlying principles had not been given thor- ough and scientific examination. It therefore seems to me that, in respect to no question possessing such fundamental and far-reaching consequences in its in- fluence upon our institutions and upon our constitu- tional rights, should we feel it is improper to ask or unjustifiable to expect a thorough and scientific re- examination of the principles on which previous de- cisions have rested. It is, therefore, proposed to re-examine this question on principle, unembarrassed by a consideration of the precedents which have been made. This would seem to be especially justifiable where the principles asserted in respect to governmental reg- ulation involve consequences so far reaching as prac- tically to involve throughout the country the success or failure of railroad operations in private hands, and, consequently, the success or failure of private owner- 35 ship of railroad property. In respect to this long and short haul clause, it must be noted that an inflexible rule established by Congress, forbidding a lower charge for the longer haul, would, if valid, as shown by statistics offered by the Louisville & Nashville Eail- road Company to the Interstate Commerce Commis- sion some years ago, deprive that company of one- third of its entire freight traffic, and it is now esti- mated, by competent authority, that the rule in ques- tion would involve a deprivation of the carriers in southeastern territory of at least forty per cent of their freight traffic. When these enormous figures are considered, the criticism of the Kentucky case hereinbefore mentioned, made by the Hon. Charles G. Washburn, of Massachusetts, on the floor of the House, when this clause was under considera- tion, becomes all the more striking. He said: **The Kentucky law applied to perhaps one- fourth of the railroad business in the State. The mileage of railroads in Kentucky was about one and one-half per cent of the total mileage of the United States. We may say, therefore, roughly speaking, that the business to which the Kentucky long and short haul law applied, was less than one-half of one per cent of the total business of the railroads in the United States.'' Record, p. 4993. A court, out of deference to local conditions in a State, and actuated by a desire to uphold the State's 36 laws, might possibly view with unconcern an effect so comparatively trivial on the business of the country, but would feel it necessary to re-examine the question if brought face to face with ruinous consequences to so large a portion of the business of the transportation companies as would be subject to the operation of this law of Congress. In view of these immense consequences, we feel jus« tified in re-examining this question on principle. In pursuing this inquiry, there are certain funda- mental propositions which do not seem, either in the light of reason or in the light of authority, to be open to question. It seems to be beyond question that the use of prop- erty is property, and that to deprive a carrier of the use of its property is to deprive it of the property itself. This is not only true in fact, but has been re- peatedly held by the Supreme Court. Thus it was said by that court in Chicago, Milwau- kee & St. Paul Railway Co. vs, Minnesota, 134 U. S., 458: **If the company is deprived of the power of charging reasonable rates for the use of its property, and such deprivation takes place in the absence of an investigation by judicial ma- chinery, it is deprived of the lawful use of its property, and thus, in substance and effect, of the property itself, without due process of law and in violation of the Constitution of the United States; and in so far as it is thus de- prived, while other persons are permitted to re- 37 ceive reasonable profits upon their invested capital, the company is deprived of the equal protection of the laws." And in Cleveland, etc., vs. Backus, 154 U. S., 445, it is said: **The value of property results from the use to which it is put, and varies with the profitable- ness of that use, present and prospective, actual and anticipated. There is no pecuniary value outside of that which results from such use." And in Monongahela Navigation Co. vs. United States, 148 U. S., 328, the court says : '*The value of property, generally speaking, is determined by its productiveness — the profits which its use brings to the owner." Again: **For each separate use of one's property by others, the owner is entitled to a reasonable com- pensation, and the number and amount of such uses determines the productiveness and the earnings of the property, and therefore, largely its value." The same doctrine is stated in the case of In re Mar- shall, 102 Fed., 323, where it is said: **The constitutional guaranty, said the Court of Appeals of New York in Re Jacobs, 98 N. Y., 105, that no person shall be deprived of prop- erty without due process of law, may be violated without the physical taking of property for pub- 38 lie or private use. Property may be destroyed or its value may be annihilated. It is owned and kept for some useful purpose, and it has no value unless it can be used. Its capability for enjoyment and adaptability to some use are es- sential characteristics and attributes without which property cannot be conceived, and hence any law which destroys it or its value, or takes away any of its essential attributes, deprives the owner of his property.'' It would seem, therefore, unquestionable that every owner of property has a property right, protected by the Constitution, to use it in every legitimate way. It would seem equally certain that the use of prop- erty which is inherently proper and in the public in- terest, cannot be made illegal by a statute, for, if it could be thus made illegal, all that a legislature would have to do in order to confiscate property would be to declare illegal all uses to which it might be put, and, by force of such statutory declaration, the owner of the property would be effectively deprived of all protec- tion from the Constitution. That a statute cannot make a use of property illegal which is wholly proper, is shown by innumerable decisions of the Supreme Court of the United States. For example, many of the States have passed laws declaring that it shall be illegal for railroads to use their property for more than a certain designated rate. The Supreme Court has repeatedly held that this legislative declaration of what would be illegal did not make it illegal con- 39 trary to the fact, because a property right was in- volved and the effect of snch holding would be to de- prive the carrier of the beneficial use of its property, in violation of the Constitution. This same proposi-* tion is established by all the cases defining the proper scope and use of the police power. In respect to this, I print in the appendix, as Appen- dix A, a valuable note made by my assistant, Mr. John K. Graves. It is a sound principle of economics, and is admitted by both the Interstate Commerce Commission and by the Supreme Court of the United States, that, in no case where substantial competition exists, can a rail- road property be used except in recognition of, and in obedience to, the law of competition. As the chairman of the committee, who introduced the original Inter- state Commerce Bill, stated on the floor: **It (the law of competition) is stronger than any law we can make. ' ' Thus it is stated by Judge Cooley : **Low rates are a necessity of the situation, and if railroads compete with water transporta- tion, either on the ocean or on the navigable rivers, they have no choice but to accept such rates. To compel the roads to observe strictly the general rule laid down by the fourth section would necessitate their abandonment of some classes of business in which their competition with water transportation is now of public im- portance. ' ' 40 And again: *'The fact still remains that they must either be allowed to compete with vessel owners and make low charges for the purpose, or they must leave vessel owners in possession of the busi- ness without the check upon charges which com- petition would afford.*' This same view is approved by the Supreme Court of the United States. It says : ^^It must also be conceded that the defendant would lose the foreign traffic, by reason of the competition referred to, and the revenue de- rived therefrom, unless it carries at the lower rates and by so doing is enabled to get part of it.** Texas & Pacific Ey. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 236. This is also apparent from the following decisions of the Supreme Court : Interstate Com. Com*n vs, Alabama Midland Ry. Co., 168 U. S., 144; Louisville & Nashville R. R. Co. vs. Behlmer, 175U. S., 653; East. Tenn., etc., Ry. Co. vs. Interstate Com. Com*n, 181 U. S., 1. It is likewise true that this use of a carrier's prop- erty, in accordance with and in obedience to an irre- sistible law of economics, is right in itself and is in the interest of the public. 41 In connection with this view of the subject, the fol- lowing expressions from Judge Cooley in the Louis- ville & Nashville case, examined by the Commission in 1887, are of interest : "Every railroad company ought, when it is practicable, to so arrange its tariffs that the bur- den upon freights shall be proportional on all portions of its line and with a view to revenue sufficient to meet all the items of current ex- pense, including the cost of keeping up the road, buildings, and equipment, and of returning a fair profit to owners. But it is obvious that, in some cases, when there is water competition at leading points, it may be impossible to make some portion of the traffic pay its equal propor- tion of the whole cost. If it can then be made to pay anything toward the cost, above what the taking of it would add to the expense, the rail- road ought not, in general, to be forced to reject it, since the surplus, under such circumstances, would be profit. As has been tersely said by M. de la Gournerie, formerly inspector-general of bridges and railways in France, a railroad ^ ought not to neglect any traffic of a kind that will increase its receipts more than its ex- penses ' ; and long-haul traffic which can only be had on these terms may sometimes be taken without wronging any one, when, to carry all traffic, or even the major part of it, at the like rates, would be simply ruinous. But we desire to apply generally to every kind of competition herein discussed the observation above made, that when competition leads to the transporta- tion of property below actual cost, fairly com- 42 puted, it ceases to be legitimate. Fair and reasonable competition is a public benefit; ex- cessive and unreasonable competition is a public injury. Competition is to be regulated, not abolished. The other sections of the law of themselves imply ample authority for its regu- lation, and, in connection with the fourth sec- tion, support the interpretation that it is wholly inadmissible to press competition to a point where expenses are increased beyond the in- crease of income.^' And in one of the quotations above made from this same opinion it is shown that — **to compel roads to observe strictly the general rule laid down by the fourth section would ne- cessitate their abandonment of some classes of business in which their competition with water transportation is now of public importance.'' And as is said by the Supreme Court : **It is self-evident that many cases may and do arise where, although the object of the car- riers is to secure the traffic for their own pur- poses and upon their own lines, yet, neverthe- less, the very fact that they seek, by the charges they make, to secure it, operates in the interests of the public.'' Texas & Pacific Ey. Co. vs. Int. Com. Com., 162 U. S., 218. The main fact which makes the participation of the rail carrier in this competitive traffic to the interest of the public is that, if a carrier is excluded from any 43 material portion of traffic which pays a margin of profit, then the loss which such exclusion involves must be put on the remaining portion of its traffic and in- crease the cost to the public interested in such re- mainder. This fact is thus stated by Justice White, in the case of East Tennessee, etc., Ey. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 181 U. S., 20: ** Applying the principle to which we have ad- verted to the condition as above stated, it is ap- parent that if the carrier was prevented under the circumstances from meeting the competitive rate at Nashville, when it could be done at a margin of profit over the cost of transportation, it would produce the very discrimination which would spring from allowing the carrier to meet a competitive rate where the traffic must be car- ried at an actual loss. To compel the carriers to desist from all Nashville traffic under the cir- cumstances stated would simply result in de- flecting the traffic to Nashville to other routes, and thus entail upon the carriers who were in- hibited from meeting the competition, although they could do so at a margin of profit, the loss which would arise from the disappearance of such business, without anywise benefiting the public." In view of the foregoing considerations, and of all the decisions of the Supreme Court, the following prin- ciples may be stated as true, as self-evident and as fun- damental : 44 First. That the use of property is property within the meaning of the Fifth Amendment to the Consti- tution ; Second. That a use of property is legitimate which is in accordance with, and in obedience to, a fair rule of trade and an irresistible law of economics; Third. That such use is not only proper and legiti- mate in itself, but is in the interest of the public; Fourth. That such use cannot be taken away from a carrier by legislation of Congress without a viola- tion of the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution. The case may be stated thus : A carrier, in accordance with the law, has con- structed a railroad between two competitive points through a number of non-competitive points. It is not the short rail line. It is in competition with water carriers on the ocean which are not subject to the Act to Regulate Commerce. It is subject to the con- trolling competition of short line rail carriers. It is subject to controlling competition of com- - modities and of markets. It seeks to partici- pate in competitive traffic and to make a rate between its competitive points lower than to inter- mediate points, which gives to it some margin of profit and which is made necessary by the competitive condi- tions. All its rates to intermediate non-competitive points are reasonable in and of themselves. The cir- cumstances of the service between the competitive points so differ from the circumstances of the service 45 to intermediate non-competitive points that the differ- ence in charge **is in exact conformity with the differ- ence of circumstances/' In such a case could Con- gress prevent the carrier from carrying between the two competitive points at the rate mentioned? In considering this question it must be remembered that Congress, in the language of Judge Cooley, has studiously omitted to bring the steamboat and other independent water lines within its control and must, therefore, have contemplated and approved the con- tinuance of that kind of competition. It is likewise spending millions of dollars annually of the public money in the improvement of rivers and harbors for the purpose of making such competition more substantial and effective. Under the act, likewise, the rate in question is per- mitted and is possible over the shorter line of rail- road. Moreover, the rate is necessary to the carrier in question because of economic conditions produced at competitive points by competition of products and competition of markets. If, under these circumstances, the carrier can be prevented from carrying between the two competitive points at the rate proposed, it is in effect prevented from using its property at all be- tween those points. It is certainly prevented from using it in fair recognition of, and in obedience to, a controlling economic law, which Congress does not undertake to alter or destroy, but the application of which to the conditions supposed, it is, by appropri- 46 ations from the public treasury, fostering and building up. If, therefore. Congress has the consti- tutional power to prevent this legitimate commercial use of property, it has in practical effect the power of confiscation. The only alternative to this consequence would be to say that Congress does not prevent the use of the carrier's property between two competitive points at a competitive rate, but in such case only requires that the intermediate rate should be made no higher. This, however, in the case supposed, would simply shift the method of confiscation. While permitting the carrier to participate in the competitive trafiic at the rates found necessary to such participation, and thus not confiscating that use, the effect would be to deprive the carrier, in the case supposed, of the right to charge reasonable, and not unduly discriminatory rates, to intermediate points. This latter right is a right of property as distinctly as the other, and in preventing the use of the property at intermediate points at reasonable rates Congress would be taking away from the carrier a legitimate use of its property. In reaching this conclusion, I am not forgetful of the fact that the decisions thus far have made the cri- terion of confiscation to be a fair return upon the car- rier's property, and have not yet adopted as a cri- terion a fair compensation for each individual service. In respect to this, however, it should be remarked again that the extent of governmental regulation has 47 become so far reaching, and both its extent and its limitations so important, that the principles which have heretofore been announced in respect to it are legitimately entitled to a re-examination in the light of the greater governmental authority which is claimed. On principle it is true, as has been announced by the Supreme Court, that — **If a company is deprived of the power of charging reasonable rates for the use of its property, and such deprivation takes place in the absence of an investigation by judicial ma- chinery, it is deprived of the lawful use of its property, and thus, in substance and effect, of the property itself (Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Eailway Co. vs. Minn., 134 U. S., 458); and that — **for each separate use of one's property by others, the owner is entitled to a reasonable compensation, and the number and amount of such uses determines the productiveness and the earnings of the property, and, therefore, largely its value *' (Monongahela Nav. Co. vs. United' States, 184 U. S., 328). In other words, a carrier has a right to do business ; it has a right to charge for each separate service that which is reasonable compensation therefor, and the legislature may not deny it such reasonable com- pensation and may not interfere simply because out of the multitude of its transactions the amount of its profits is large. 48 The rule by which the value of all other property than that subjected to a public use is arrived at is to ascertain its reasonable earning capacity, and, by capitalizing that, to ascertain the property value. The rule heretofore acted on by the courts, in re- spect to properties subjected to a public use, is that the value of the property must be first arrived at, and from that deduce its reasonable earning capacity. An arbitrary reversal of the method applicable to all other property, whether by legislative authority or by judicial decree, is, as applied to this one class of prop- erty, a manifest deprivation of a valuable interest in property, as well as a denial of the equal protection of the laws. There can be no difference between prop- erty devoted to a public use and other private prop- erty except such difference as is measured by the legitimate consequences of the public use. The in- terest of the public, in the property of a carrier and in its transactions, can only be that the ' car- rier shall not charge more for a service than a reasonable compensation therefor; that it shall not unduly discriminate as between persons or localities or commodities, or subject any of them to undue prejudice or disadvantage, and that its facilities shall be adequate. Every power of regula- tion asserted by the Government, in respect to private property subject to a public use, must be measured and tested by whether or not it legitimately tends to secure one or other of these results. If the carrier performs faithfully these three duties, then, subject to them, its property is its own and is beyond the reach of governmental interference. In other words, when the thing is done that is required by the Act to Regulate Commerce to be done by the Commission, namely, when there is a determination, in the language of the first section, that the rate of the carrier is just and reasonable for the service rendered, and, as re- quired by other sections, that there is no unjust dis- crimination as between persons or localities or com- modities, then there exists a property right in the carrier to charge and receive this reasonable rate, and its right to do so cannot be taken away or affected by the amount of the return upon its property. It may be that it cannot make a reasonable return on its prop- erty by charging reasonable rates. If so, the Govern- ment need not and cannot give it that power. It may be that, by reason of favorable and wise design and good management, it is able, by charging a reasonable rate for each of its services, to make a large profit on the amount>invested. This profit in every one of its factors is beyond the reach of governmental power, and is the private property of the owners. If the subject be viewed from another standpoint the result is the same. Let us suppose a case where the return upon a prop- erty is not more than a reasonable return on the amount invested, and let us suppose that this return results from a system of rates, some of which are too 4— E 50 • low and some of which are too high. In such a case the carrier cannot justify those that are too high by showing that the average is right, for that would be throwing unjustly on the class of traffic bearing the rates which are too high a burden unjustly taken from the other class of traffic on which the charges are un duly low. The Government could not maintain or re- quire rates that are too low for the service on the ground that other rates of the carrier are too high, and that the average makes only a proper return upon the property, for that would be creating an unlawful dis- crimination between the two classes of traffic to the prejudice of those that were charged too much. It is, therefore, manifest that any philosophic and just reg ulation of this subject, in which the interests of the public are duly preserved, and in which the property rights of the carrier are duly respected, must arise from a proper and just adjustment of each rate to each service. This necessity grows out of the nature of the situation. It is no answer to say that it is difficult to de- termine what is a reasonable compensation for the service. This very thing is required of the Interstate Commerce Commission by the Act to Regulate Com- merce whenever the reasonableness and justice of a rate is brought to its consideration. The statute re- quires it to determine whether that rate is just and reasonable for the service. It is manifestly impossi- ble, in respect to any individual rate, for the Commis- 51 sion to be guided by the value of the property and the total returns therefrom. It is not denied that the de- termination of the question of reasonableness is diffi- cult, but the application of a false standard is never justified by the difficulty of applying the true one, and in this connection it is apparent that Congress itself has applied the true one in the Act to Regulate Com- merce. If the law-making body can ascertain and de- clare what rate is reasonable, there is no reason why the courts, with methods at least equally adequate, should not be able to do so. The suggestion made in this note is not as to the application of a new standard, but merely that, when the stand- ard created by Congress itself in respect to the powers of the Interstate Commerce Commis- sion is applied, the result of the proper application of that standard is to bring the case within the protec- tion of the Constitution, and not to give it merely a statutory sanction. Whether or not the Commission has done this in any case is a judicial question. In respect to the difficulty of the application of this standard, it must likewise be remembered that it is no more difficult to apply the test of reasonableness to a rate than it is to apply it to most other services. The whole principle of quantum meruit at the common law is built up on the necessity of determining, by courts and juries, what is reasonable, and the same test of what is reasonable in respect to any other service would apply in the determination of what is reasonable 52 in respect to the service of a carrier. The test of usage, the test of comparison, the test of expert opin- ion, the test of effect npon commerce and upon the proper distribution of burdens and advantages be- tween all interested, and other tests which might be enumerated, would apply to and determine the question of reasonableness in such a case. As interesting in this connection, I print in the ap- pendix, as Appendix B, an extract from a recent ad- dress of Mr. W. W. Finley, President of Southern Eail- way Company. The foregoing considerations seem to justify the conclusion that an inflexible rule forbidding a smaller charge for the longer distance, notwithstanding the fact that the smaller charge for the longer distance would be justified by the laws of trade and necessitated by economic forces, would be an unconstitutional in- vasion of the property rights of the carrier. If this be true, and if likewise true that an unre- stricted and unmeasured discretion in the Commission would be an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power, then it would seem that the only constitutional interpretation of the fourth section as amended would be that given in the first part of this paper, and it is believed that the interpretation there given is the proper construction of the law. EespectfuUy submitted. Alfred P. Thom. WASHmoTON, D. C, February, 1911. APPENDIX A. THE FEDERAL LONG AND SHORT HAUL CLAUSE AND THE FIFTH AMENDMENT. Notes by John K. Graves. Mr. Thom : The question submitted is, whether, assuming that the long and short haul clause (Clause 4 of the Act to Regulate Commerce) gives the Commission arbitrary power to allow or refuse to allow the carrier to charge less for the haul to the longer distance destination than for the haul to the shorter distance point, even though controlling competition exist at the longer distance point, the clause, as so construed, violates the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution of the United States. There will not be considered in these notes any ques- tion with respect to the effect of any action of the Commission under the clause, as resulting in an in- adequate return to the carrier upon the value of its entire property; and the short-haul rate will be assumed to be reasonable. Also, no question is raised as to delegation of legislative power. **The clause'' as hereinafter used, without explanation, will mean the Federal long and short haul clause construed as above indicated. The question put seems to resolve itself into whether Congress can enact a rigid long and short haul clause. The clause would give the Conmiission arbitrary and (63) 54 discretionary power in the premises, which means that there could be no review of its action in the courts. Whether, under the Minnesota case in 134 U. S., such an enactment could stand, depends upon whether the constitutional rights of the carrier could be taken away by any action of the Commission which the clause gives it the power to take. The clause em- powers the Commission to refuse to allow the carrier to charge less to the longer distance point, though con- trolling competition exists there, and though the shorter distance rate is reasonable in and of itself, thus inevitably depriving the carrier of traffic to the longer distance point. If such an exercise of power by the agent of Congress violates the Fifth Amend- ment, then the act authorizing such exercise of power must fall. It will not do to undertake to save the act, as did the Kentucky Court of Appeals in the case of Louisville & Nashville Eailroad Co. vs. Common- wealth, 51 S. W., 164, where, in defending the Ken- tucky constitutional provision (which is identical with the Federal long and short haul clause as it was be- fore the recent amendment) against the charge that it violated the Fourteenth Amendment if controlling competition at the longer distance point were held (as it had been by the Kentucky courts) not to create dis- similar circumstances, the court sustained the pro- vision on the theory that the Commission was empowered to make any exception that it desired, and that it was not to be supposed that it would do injustice to the carrier. If the exercise of the discretion reposed in the Commission could in any case deprive the carrier of its constitu- tionar rights, then the Kentucky constitutional pro- vision should have been wiped out, as authorizing an invasion of the carrier's constitutional rights without recourse to the refuge of the courts, if the Minnesota 55 case is still of any efficacy and if this land can still boast a government of laws, not of men. If the Supreme Court was right in condemning the statute in United States vs. Eeese, 92 U. S., 214, 221, where Chief Justice Waite remarked that, '*It would certainly be dangerous if the legis- lature could set a net large enough to catch all possible offenders and leave it to the courts to step inside and say who could be rightfully de- tained and who should be set at large, ' ' an act of Congress giving free rein to an administra- tive body not capable of affording due process of law to take away property rights must be condenmed. The question to be determined is, then. Would a rigid long and short haul clause enacted by Congress deprive the carrier of its property in violation of the Fifth Amendment? There is a very unpleasant decision in 183 U. S. (p. 503) — Louisville & Nashville E. Co. vs. Kentucky — involving the validity, under the Fourteenth Amend- ment, of the Kentucky constitutional provision, which is identical with the Federal clause as it existed prior to the recent amendment. As hereinbefore indicated, the Kentucky courts had excluded controlling competi- tion at the long distance point as a circumstance cre- ating dissimilarity of conditions. The Supreme Court upheld the clause as thus construed, saying (p. 514) : * * The evil sought to be prevented was the use of public highways in such a manner as to pre- fer, by difference of rates, one locality to another, and the remedy adopted by the State was to declare such preferences illegal, and to prohibit any person, corporation, or common carrier from resorting to them. That remedy 56 included in its scope every one, without dis- tinction, whose calling, public in its character, gave an opportunity to do the mischief which the State desired to prevent. The practical in- efficiency of this remedy to reach the desired end, and the resulting injury to the welfare of both the producers and the consumers of an article like coal, when brought into competition with coal brought from without the State, are strongly urged in behalf of the plaintiff in error; but, however well founded such objec- tions may be, they go to the wisdom and policy of the enactment, not to its validity in a Federal point of view.'* Let us consider that the principles involved did not receive that careful consideration which their impor- tance demanded (and the opinion indicates great con- fusion in the mind of the court), and consider those ])rinciples in the light of reason and the other decisions of the courts. In the first place, the clause may be assumed to be within the general bounds of the powers conferred on Congress by the commerce clause. It seems clear that the purpose of the enactment is to destroy and prevent discrimination, and that that is its only purpose. See the Kentucky case in 183 U. S., supra; Texas & Pacific Ry. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 184, 197. It cannot be denied that such purpose is a proper one. The validity, then, of the clause will depend upon the answer to the question, Is the enactment reason- able, or is it arbitrary? In order for an act to successfully meet this test, it must be adapted to the accomplishment of the end sought (it having been assumed that its purpose is 57 legitimate), and in accomplishing such end, the re- sults must not be so destructive as to plainly and de- cisively outweigh the good it is calculated to do. The more important the accomplishment of the purposes of an act, and the better adapted the act is to accom- plish such purposes, the more incidental damage it may do without thereby overstepping constitutional bounds. In McCulloch vs. Maryland, 4 Wheat., 316, 421, 423, Chief Justice Marshall declared : *^The sound construction of the Constitution must allow to the national legislature that dis- cretion, with respect to the means by which the powers it confers are to be carried into execu- tion, which will enable that body to perform the high duties assigned to it, in the manner most beneficial to the people. Let the end be legiti- mate, let it be within the scope of the Constitu- tion, and all means which are appropriate, which are plainly adapted to that end, which are not prohibited, but consist with the letter and spiri of the Constitution, are constitutional."" Again : *^ Where the law is not prohibited, and is really calculated to effect any of the objects en- trusted to the Government, to undertake here to inquire into the degree of its necessity, would be to pass the line which circumscribes the judi- cial department, and to tread on legislative ground. ' ' Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Brimson, 154 U. S., 447, illustrates the principle that legislative en- actments to be sustained must be designed to ac- 58 complish the proper ends of government and must in fact be adapted to the accomplishment of such ends. In that case the court declared that the prohibition of discriminations in the matter of interstate rates was a proper exercise of the power of Congress under the commerce clause, and that the provisions of section 12 of the act, empowering the Commission to inquire into the management of the business of carriers sub- ject to the act, and to subpoena witnesses to testify concerning the subjects involved in the act, were ''plainly adapted to the objects intended to be ac- complished. ' ' '' Interpreting the Interstate Commerce Act as ap plicable," said the court, **and as intended to apply, only to matters involved in the regulation of com- merce, and which Congress may rightfully subject to investigation by a commission established for the pur- pose of enforcing that act, we are unable to say that its provisions are not appropriate and plainly adapted to the protection of interstate commerce from burdens that are or may be, directly or indirectly, imposed upon it by means of unjust and unreasonable discrimi- nations, charges, and preferences. Congress is not lim- ited in its employment of means to those that are abso- lutely essential to the accomplishment of objects within the scope of the powers granted to it. It is a settled principle of constitutional law that 'the government which has a right to do an act, and has imposed on it the duty of performing that act, must, according to the dictates of reason, be allowed to select the means ; and those who contend that it may not select any appro- priate means, that one particular mode of effecting the object is excepted, take upon themselves the bur- den of establishing that exception.' 4 Wheat., 316, 409.'' Where the enactment, although its purpose may be 59 to promote the interests of the public, is so destructive of individual rights as plainly to outweigh the sup- posed advantages accruing from its operation, the courts will strike it down. A good illustration of this is found in the cases on rate regulation. Whatever may be the true theory with respect to Government control over railroad rates, the theory that is now and has for a long time been applied by the courts is that where an enactment fixing rates reaches the point where the carrier is not allowed an adequate return upon the value of its prop- erty, such enactment is considered not to be a regula- tion adapted to the accomplishment of a proper public purpose, and is regarded as confiscatory. This is practically the application of the principle of reason- ableness. In Eailroad Commission Cases, 116 U. S., 307, Chief Justice Waite said that — *' under pretense of regulating fares on trains the State cannot require a railroad corporation to carry persons or property without reward, neither can it do that which in law amounts to the taking of private property for public use without just compensation or without due pro- cess of law.'' In the Eeagan case (154 U. S., 362, 399) it was de- clared that ' * it is within the scope of judicial power and a part of judicial duty to restrain anything which, in the form of a regulation of rates, operates to deny to the owners of property invested in the business of transportation that equal protection which is the constitutional right of i\\] owners of other property.'' 60 In Smyth vs, Ames, 169 U. S., these cases are re- ferred to by the court, and it again declares that the Federal Constitution forbids legislation, ^^in whatever form it may be enacted, '' by which a person's property is taken from him without compensation, and that ^ * the forms of law and the machinery of government, with all their reach and power, must, in their actual work- ings, stop on the hither side of unnecessary and un- compensated taking or destruction of any private property legally acquired and legally held.'' Thus, if a rate-fixing statute goes beyond the limit of regulation, it ceases to be adapted to proper govern- mental purposes, and is condemned as an arbitrary interference by the Government with property rights. In Lochner vs. New York, 198 U. S., 45, the Supreme Court struck down a statute of New York providing that employees in bakeries should not be required or permitted to work more than 10 hours a day, the court saying (pp. 56-57) : **It must, of course, be conceded that there is a limit to the valid exercise of the police power by the State. There is no dispute con- cerning this general proposition. Otherwise the Fourteenth Amendment would have no effi- cacy and the legislatures of the States would have unbounded power, and it would be enough to say that any piece of legislation was enacted to conserve the morals, the health or the safety of the people; such legislation would be valid, no matter how absolutely without foundation the claim might be. The claim of the police power would be a mere pretext — become another and delusive name for the supreme sovereignty of the State to be exercised free from constitutional restraint. This is not con- tended for. In every case that comes before 61 this court, therefore, where legislation of this character is concerned and where the protection of the Federal Constitution is sought, the ques- tion necessarily arises: Is this a fair, reason- able and appropriate exercise of the police power of the State, or is it an unreasonable, un- necessary and arbitrary interference with the right of the individual to his personal liberty or to enter into those contracts in relation to labor which may seem to him appropriate or necessary for the support of himself and his family? Of course the liberty of contract re- lating to labor includes both parties to it. The one has as much right to purchase as the other to sell labor. **This is not a question of substituting the judgment of the court for that of the legislature. If the act be within the power of the State it is valid, although the judgment of the court might be totally opposed to the enactment of such a law. But the question would still remam: Is it within the police power of the State? An^l that question must be answered by the court.'' Again (pp. 57-8) : **It is a question of which of two powers or rights shall prevail — the power of the State to legislate or the right of the individual to iibertv of person and freedom of contract. The mere assertion that the subject relates though but in a remote degree to the public health does not necessarily render the enactment valid. The act must have a more direct relation, as a means to an end, and the end itself must be appro- priate and legitimate, before an act can be held to be valid which interferes with the general 62 right of an individual to be free in his person and in his power to contract in relation to his own labor.'' Again (p. 61) :• * * Statutes of the nature of that under review, limiting the hours in which grown and intelli- gent men may labor to earn their living, are mere meddlesome interferences with the rights of the individual, and they are not saved from condemnation by the claim that they are passed in the exercise of the police power and upon the subject of the health of the individual whose rights are interfered with, unless, there be some fair ground, reasonable in and of itself, to say that there is material danger to the pub- lic health or to the health of the employees, if the hours of labor are not curtailed." In Atlantic Coast Line E. Co. vs. North Carolina Corporation Commission (Selma Connection Case), 206 U. S., 1, the Supreme Court (per Justice White) said (p. 20) : **As the public power to regulate railways and the private right of ownership of such prop- erty coexist and do not the one destroy the other, it has been settled that the right of own- ership of railway property, like other property rights, finds protection in constitutional guar- anties, and, therefore, wherever the power of regulation is exerted in such an arbitrary and unreasonable way as to cause it to be in effect not a regulation, but an infringement upon the right of ownership, such an exertion of power is void because repugnant to the due process 63 and equal protection clauses of the 14th Amend ment. ' ' The court upheld the statute, although it was shown that the operation of the train would not be profitable, saying (p. 27) : ''Of course the fact that the furnishing of a necessary facility ordered may occasion an in- cidental pecuniary loss is an important criteria (sic) to be taken into view in determining the reasonableness of the order, but it is not the only one.'' See Missouri Pacific E. Co. vs. Kansas, 216 U. S., 262; Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Northern Pacific E. Co., 216 U. S., 538. In C, B. & Q. E. Co. vs. Drainage Commissioners, 200 XJ. S., 561, where an act of Illinois under which the railroad was required to rebuild its bridge over a creek, made necessary by its enlargement by the Drain- age Commission, was upheld by the Supreme Court, the court thus laid down the principle governing the case (p. 592) : ''The validity of a police regulation, whether established directly by the State or by some public body acting under its sanction, must de- pend upon the circumstances of each case and the character of the regulation, whether arbi- trary or reasonable and whether really designed to accomplish a legitimate public purpose." It clearly appears from the foregoing cases that if a rigid long and short haul clause is arbitrary and un- reasonable because not adapted to effect a legitimate public purpose, or because so burdensome upon 64 the carrier as decisively to outweigh any advantage that may accrue to the public from it, it must be con- demned. Let us, then, inquire whether the clause is adapted to the accomplishment of legitimate public ob- jects, or whether it cannot be considered as so adapted because arbitrarily interfering with the property rights of the carrier. The construction originally put upon the long and short haul clause by the Commission denied the efficacy of competition at the longer distance point with other carriers subject to the Act as producing a dissimilarity of circumstances authorizing a lower rate to the longer distance point. This construction of the Act was de- molished by the Supreme Court. Cincinnati, N. 0. & T. P. E. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 184; Texas & Pacific Eailway Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 197; Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Alabama Midland E. Co., 168 U. S., 144; Louisville & Nashville E. Co. vs. Behl- mer, 175 U. S., 648. In overruling the position taken by the Commission, the Supreme Court in effect declared that it was unable to adopt a construction of the Act that would interfere with and destroy commerce and unnecessarily inter- fere with the business of the carriers. Texas & Pacific E. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Com- mission, supra, involved the validity of an order of the Interstate Commerce Commission requiring the de- fendant company to desist from carrying import traf- fic from port to destination at a less rate than it car- ried inland traffic between such points. While the case involved the construction of section 3, the principles laid down are equally applicable to section 4. Indeed, the purposes of the entire Act were reviewed by the court. At page 211, the court (by Justice Shiras) said: 65 ' ' So, too, it could not be readily supposed that Congress intended, when regulating such com- merce, to interfere with and interrupt, much less destroy, sources of trade and commerce already existing, nor to overlook the property rights of those who had money invested in the railroads of the country, nor to disregard the interests of the consumers, to furnish whom with merchan- dise is one of the principal objects of all systems of transportation.'^ Again, on page 218: *^We think that Congress has here pointed out that, in considering questions of this sort, the Commission is not only to consider the wishes and interests of the shippers and mer- chants of large cities, but to consider also the desire and advantage of the carriers in securing special forms of traffic, and the interest of the public that the carriers should secure that traffic, rather than abandon it, or not attempt to secure it. It is self-evident that many cases may and do arise where, although the object of the car- riers is to secure the traffic for their own pur- poses and upon their own lines, yet, neverthe- less, the very fact that they seek, by the charges they make, to secure it, operates in the interests of the public. '' Again (p. 219) : ^'Commerce, in its largest sense, must be deemed to be one of the most important subjects of legislation, and an intention to promote and facilitate it, and not to hamper or destroy it, is naturally to be attributed to Congress. The 5— E 66 very terms of the statute, that charges must be reasonable^ that discrimination must not be un- just, and that preference or advantage to any particular person, firm, corporation, or locality must not be undue or unreasonable, necessarily imply that strict uniformity is not to be en- forced; but that all circumstances and condi- tions which reasonable men would regard as affecting the welfare of the carrying companies, and of the producers, shippers, and consumers, should be considered by a tribunal appointed to carry into effect and enforce the provisions of the act." On page 222 the court declared that the order of the Commission created the very discrimination which it was the object of the act to destroy : **The effort of the Commission, by a rigid general order, to deprive the inland consumers of the advantage of through rates, and to thus give an advantage to the traders and manufac- turers of the large seaboard cities, seems to cre- ate the very mischief which it was one of the ob- jects of the act to remedy.'* The court reviewed the English cases arising out of the English act from which section 3 of the Act to Regulate Commerce was taken. It called attention to the decision in Phipps vs. London & Northwestern Railway, 2 Q. B. D., 1892, 229, where a violation of the long and short haul principle, caused by controlling competition at the longer distance point, was claimed to constitute an undue discrimination. The following language of Lord Herschell is quoted : 67 * * Of course, if the circumstances so differ that the difference of charge is in exact conformity with the difference of circumstances, there would be no preference at all. * ' The court approves the language of Lord Selborne, in Denaby Main Colliery Company vs. Manchester, etc., Railway Co., 3 Railway and Canal Traffic Cases, 426, where he said : ^*It is said that it is unfair to the trader who is nearer the market that he should enjoy the full benefit of the advantage to be derived from his geographical situation at a point on the rail- way nearer the market than his fellow-trader who trades at a point more distant ; but I cannot see, looking at the matter as between the two traders, why the advantageous position of the one trader in having his works so placed that he has two competitive routes is not as much a circumstance to be taken into consideration as the geographical position of the other trader, who, though he has not the advantage of compe- tition, is situated at a point on the line geo- graphically nearer the market. Why the local situation in regard to its proximity to the mar- ket is to be the only consideration to be taken into account in dealing with the matter as a matter of what is reasonable and right as be- tween the two traders, I cannot understand. * * * One class of cases, unquestionably in- tended to be covered by the section, is that in which traffic from a distance, of a character that competes with traffic nearer the market, is charged low rates, because unless such low rates were charged, it would not come into the market 68 at all. It is certain, unless some such principle as that were adopted, a large town would neces- sarily have its food supply greatly raised in price. So that, although the object of the com- pany is simply to get the traffic, the public have an interest in their getting the traffic and allow- ing the carriage at a rate which will render that traffic possible, and so bring the goods at a cheaper rate, and one which makes it possible for those at a greater distance to compete with those situate nearer to it. * * * ** Suppose that to insist on absolutely equal rates would practically exclude one of the two railways from the traffic, it is obvious that these members of the public who are in the neighbor- hood where they can have the benefit of this competition, would be prejudiced by any such proceedings. And, further, inasmuch as com- petition undoubtedly tends to diminution of charges, and the charge of carriage is one which ultimately falls upon the consumer, it is obvious that the public have an interest in the proceed- ings under this act of Parliament not being so used as to destroy a traffic which can never be secured but by some such reduction of charge, and the destruction of which would be preju- dicial to the public by tending to increase prices.'' In this case the court goes on record to the effect that an enactment causing a rigid equality of rates, though the circumstances are dissimilar, is not adapted to preventing or destroying undue discrimination, and is not in the interests of the public. It also clearly recognizes the fact that such an enactment would be 69 destructive of commerce and of the interests of the carriers engaged in such commerce. In East Tennessee, etc., R. Co. vs. Interstate Com- merce Commission, 181 U. S., 1, where Justice White delivered the opinion, the question was whether the defendant violated the long and short haul clause by carrying traffic from eastern points to Nashville through Chattanooga at a rate less than the rate to Chattanooga, the lower rate for the longer distance being induced by competition with other carriers at Nashville. The court reaffirmed its previous ruling on the question, and declared, in effect, that a contrary decision would not relieve the discrimination as against Chattanooga, and that in fact there could not be said to be discrimination by the carrier, since the conditions causing lower rates to Nashville were beyond its control. On page 18 the court said : **In a supposed case when, in the first in- stance, upon an issue as to a violation of the fourth section of the act, it is conceded or estab- lished that the rates charged to the shorter dis- tance point are just and reasonable in and of themselves, and it is also shown that the lesser rate charged for the longer haul is not wholly unremunerative and has been forced upon the carriers by competition at the longer distance point, it must result that a discrimination springing alone from a disparity in rates can- not be held, in legal effect, to be the voluntary act of the defendant carriers, and as a conse- quence the provisions of the third section of the act forbidding the making or giving of an undue or unreasonable preference or advantage will not apply. The prohibition of the third section, when that section is considered in its proper re- 70 lation, is directed against unjust discrimination or undue preference arising from the voluntary and wrongful act of the carriers complained of as having given undue preference, and does not relate to acts the result of conditions wholly beyond the control of such carriers. And special attention was directed to this view in the Behlmer case, in the passage which we have previously excerpted. To otherwise construe the statute would involve a departure from its plain language, and would be to confound cause with effect. For, if the preference occasioned in favor of a particular place by competition there gives rise to the right to charge the lesser rate to that point, it cannot be that the availing of this right is the cause of the preference, and especially is this made clear in the case sup- posed, since it is manifest that forbidding the carrier to meet the competition would not re- move the discrimination.' ' The court also pointed out that unless the carrier were permitted to make a lower rate to Nashville it would be deprived of the Nashville business. On pages 18-19 the court said : * * The only principle by which it is possible to enforce the whole statute is the construction adopted by the previous opinions of this court ; that is, that competition which is real and sub- stantial, and exercises a potential influence on rates to a particular point, brings into play the dissimilarity of circumstance and condition provided by the statute, and justifies the lesser charge to the more distant and competitive point than to the nearer and non-competitive 71 place, and that this right is not destroyed by the mere fact that incidentally the lesser charge to the competitive point may seemingly give a preference to that point, and the greater rate to the non-competitive point may apparently en- gender a discrimination against it. We say seemingly on the one hand and apparently on the other, because in the supposed cases the preference is not * undue' or the discrimination * unjust/ This is clearly so, when it is consid- ered that the lesser charge upon which both the assumption of preference and discrimination is predicated is sanctioned by the statute, which causes the competition to give rise to the right to make such lesser charge. Indeed, the find- ings of fact made by the Commission in this case leave no room for the contention that either un- due preference in favor of Nashville or unjust discrimination against Chattanooga arose merely from the act of the carriers in meeting the competition existing at Nashville. The Commission found that if the defendant carriers had not adjusted their rates to meet the com- petitive condition at Nashville, the only conse- quence would have been to deflect the traffic at the reduced rates over other lines. From this it follows that, even though the defendant car- riers had not taken the dissimilarity of circum- stance and condition into view, and had con- tinued their rates to Nashville just as if there had been no dissimilarity of circumstance and condition, the preference in favor of Nashville growing out of the conditions there existing would have remained in force and hence the discrimination which thereby arose against Chattanooga would have likewise continued to 72 exist. In other words, both Nashville and Chat- tanooga would have been exactly in the same position if the long and short haul clause had not been brought into play. ' ' Again, on page 20, the court points out that to con- strue the clause as preventing the carrier from mak- ing a lower rate to Nashville would not only not pre- vent but would create discrimination, and emphasizes the proposition that such a construction of the statute would not benefit the public, while driving the carrier out of the competitive business. After limiting its doctrine as follows: '^Take a case where the carrier cannot meet the competitive rate to a given point without transporting the merchandise at less than the cost of transportation, and therefore without bringing about a deficiency, which would have to be met by increased charges upon other busi- ness. Clearly, in such a case, the engaging in such competitive traffic would both bring about an unjust discrimination and a disregard of the public interest, since a tendency towards un- reasonable rates on other business would arise from the carriage of traffic at less than the cost of transportation to particular places.'' The court said: ''Applying the principle to which we have ad- verted to the condition as above stated, it is ap- parent that if the carrier was prevented under the circumstances from meeting the competitive rate at Nashville, when it could be done at a margin of profit over the cost of transportation, it would produce the very discrimination which 73 would spring from allowing the carrier to meet a competitive rate where the traffic must be car- ried at an actual loss. To compel the carriers to desist from all Nashville traffic under the cir- cumstances stated would simply result in de- flecting the traffic to Nashville to other routes, and thus entail upon the carriers who were in- hibited from meeting the competition, although they could do so at a margin of profit, the loss which would arise from the disappearance of such business, without anywise benefiting the public. ' ' Coming down through the decisions of the Supreme Court above cited on this question, we find that the court consistently takes the position that it cannot be supposed that Congress intended the disastrous conse- quences to carrier and public alike of construing the act as it had been originally construed by the Conunis- sion. From these decisions it would appear that the clause cannot be saved by regarding the matter as dealing with a matter wholly within the discretion of the legis- lature, as it was treated in C, B. & Q. E. Co. vs. Ander- son (Neb.), 101 N. W., 1019, in a seemingly ill-consid- ered opinion. A contrary conclusion was reached by the Circuit Court for the District of Oregon, in Ex Parte Koehler, Receiver, 23 Fed., 529, which came up upon an application of the Receiver for instructions as to whether his company should obey a statute of Oregon fixing the charges for carrying property, and providing: ^'No greater rate shall be charged for car- rying similar property a short haul than a long haul in the same direction.'^ That part of the opinion deal- ing with the long and short haul question is as follows (pp. 532-4) : 74 *'As to the matter of long and short hauls, the question, although prima facie one of dis- crimination, directly involves the right to a reasonable compensation. I assume that the State has the power to prevent a railway com- pany from discriminating between persons and places for the sake of putting one up or another down, or any other reason than the real exi- gencies of its business. Such discrimination, it seems to me, is a wanton injustice, and may therefore be i)rohibited. It violates the funda- mental maxim, which in effect forbids any one to so use his property as to injure another, sic utere tuo ut alienum non laedas. The pro- visions of the act that I have condensed in para- graphs 3, 4, and 6 aforesaid are intended to pre- vent this practice. But where the discrimina- tion is between places only, and is the result of competition with other lines or means of trans- portation, the case, I think, is different. For in- stance, the act prescribes a reasonable rate for carrying freight between Corvallis and Port- land, or from either to points intermediate thereto. But Corvallis is on the river, and has the advantage of water transportation for some months in the year. The carriage of goods by water usually costs less than by land, and as water craft are allowed to carry at a rate less than the maximum fixed for the railway, they will get all the freight from this point unless the latter is allowed to compete with it. But if, to do this, it must adopt the water rate for all the points intermediate between Portland and Corvallis, where there is no such competi- tion, it is, in effect, required to carry freight to and from such points at a less rate than that 75 which the legislature has declared to be reason- able, or else give up the business at Corvallis altogether. And the same result would follow as to Salem and other points on the east and west side lines, where there is convenient access to water transportation. **If the legislature cannot require a railway corporation, formed under the laws of the State, to carry freight for nothing, or at any less rate than a reasonable one, then it neces- sarily follows that this provision of the act can- not be enforced so far as to prevent the railway from competing with the water craft at Cor- vallis and other similarly situated points, even if in so doing they are compelled to charge less for a long haul than a short one in the same direction. It is not the fault or contrivance of the railway that compels this discrimination, but it is the necessary result of circumstances altogether beyond its control. It is not done wantonly for the purpose of putting one place up or the other down, but only to maintain its business against rival and competing lines of transportation. In other words, the matter, so far as the railway is concerned, resolves itself into a choice of evils. It must either compete with the boats during the season of water trans- portation, and carry freight below what the legislature has declared to be a reasonable rate, or abandon the field, and let its road go to rust. Nor can the shipper at the non-competing point, or over the short haul complain, so long as his goods are carried at a reasonable rate. It is not the fault of the railway that the shipper who does business at a competing point has the ad- vantage of him. It is a natural advantage 76 which he must submit to, unless the legislature will undertake • to equalize the matter by pro- hibiting the carriage of goods by water for a less rate than by rail ; and when this is done, the inequalities of distance as well as place may also be overcome by requiring goods to pay the same rate over a short haul as a long one, and then the shipper at Ashland will be as near the market as any one.'' To the effect that a rigid long and short haul rule is unconstitutional, see Chicago & Alton R. Co. vs. People, 69 111., 11. See as to the effect of competition between railroads at the longer distance point, Illinois Central R. R. Co. vs. People, 121 III, 304. To the effect that a rigid long and short haul clause does not violate the Fourteenth Amendment, see McGrew vs. Mo. Pac. Ry. Co. (Mo.), 132 S. W., 1076, 1088. It seems to me that the clause runs counter to the principles laid down in Adair vs. United States, 208 U. S., 161, where an act of Congress was condemned on two grounds, one of which was that it violated the Fifth Amendment. The act in question was section 10 of the Erdman Act, making it unlawful for carriers to discharge employees on account of membership in labor organizations, etc. At page 172, the court said: **In our opinion that section, in the particular mentioned, is an invasion of the personal lib- erty, as well as of the right of property, guar- anteed by that amendment. Such liberty and right embraces the right to make contracts for the purchase of the labor of others, and equally the right to make contracts for the sale of one 's own labor ; each right, however, being subject to the fundamental condition that no contract. 77 whatever its subject-matter, can be sustained which the law, upon reasonable grounds, forbids as inconsistent with the public interests or as hurtful to the public order or as detrimental to the common good/' Consider also Louisville & Nashville R. Co. vs. Cen- tral Stock Yards Co., 212 U. S., 132, where the court held that a provision in the Kentucky constitution re- quiring the carrier to deliver its cars to connecting carriers, and a Kentucky law requiring the carrier to accept cars offered by competing roads at arbitrary points near its terminus for the purpose of obtaining the use of its terminal facilities, violated the Fourteenth Amendment. Here the convenience of the public would have been subserved, but that consideration was held not sufficient to justify the requirement imposed upon the carrier. With respect to the clause we are considering, have endeavored to show that it is not adapted to subserving the public interest in any aspect of the case. See also Missouri Pacific R. Co. vs. Ne- braska, 217 U. S., 196, where a Nebraska statute com- pelling railroad companies to put in switches at their own expense on the application of the owners of any elevator erected within a specified limit was held to violate the Fourteenth Amendment. Even under the decision in Atlantic Coast Line vs. Riverside Mills (Carmack Amendment Case, decided January 3, 1911), which goes very far in depressing the value of stock in constitutional rights, the clause is not justified. The decision in that case was controlled by the importance attached by the Supreme Court to the public con- venience involved. The court said : *^If the power existed, and the regulation is adapted to the purposes in view, the public ad- 78 vantage justifies the discretion exercised and upholds the legislation as within the limit of the grant conferred upon Congress.'' Again : * * The power of government extends to the de- nial of the liberty of contract to the extent of forbidding or regulating any contract which is reasonably calculated to injuriously affect the public interests.'' Again : ** Having the express power to make rules for the conduct of commerce among the States, the range of Congressional discretion as to the reg- ulation best adapted to remedy a practice found inefficient or hurtful, is a wide one.'* Under the declarations of the Supreme Court, the practice of charging lower rates to long distance points is not hurtful, and the enactment is not adapted to the prevention and destruction of discrimination, which is ostensibly the purpose of the act. There can be no question that to deprive the carrier of the use of its property is to deprive it of the prop- erty itself. As said by the Supreme Court in the Min- nesota case, supra (134 U. S.), at page 458: '*If the company is deprived of the power of charging reasonable rates for the use of its property, and such deprivation takes place in the absence of investigation by judicial ma- chinery, it is deprived of the lawful use of its property, and thus, in substance and effect, of the property itself, without due process of law 79 and in violation of the Constitution of the United States; and in so far as it is thus de- prived, while other persons are permitted to re- ceive reasonable profits upon their invested cap- ital, the company is deprived of the equal pro- tection of the laws/' In Cleveland, etc., E. Co. vs. Backus, 154 U. S., 445, it is said: ^*The value of property results from the use to which it is put, and varies with the profitable- ness of that use, present and prospective, actual and anticipated. There is no pecuniary value outside of that which results from such use.*' In Monongahela Navigation Co. vs. U. S., 148 U. S., 328, the court says : **The value of property, generally speaking, is determined by its productiveness — the profits which its use brings to the owner." Again : **For each separate use of one's property by others, the owner is entitled to a reasonable compensation, and the number and amount of such uses determines the productiveness and the earnings of the property, and, therefore, largely its value." In the case of In re Marshall, 102 Fed., 323, Circuit Judge Ross said (324-5) : ^* *The constitutional guaranty,' said the Court of Appeals of New York in i^e Jacobs, 98 N. Y., 105, 'that no person shall be deprived 80 of property without due process of law, may be violated without the physical taking of property for public or private use. Property may be destroyed, or its value may be annihilated. It is owned and kept for some useful purpose, and it has no value unless it can be used. Its capa-. bility for enjoyment and adaptability to some use are essential characteristics and attributes without which property cannot be conceived, and hence any law which destroys it or its value, or takes away any of its essential attributes, deprives the owner of his property.' See also, Pumpelly vs. Green Bay Co., 13 Wall., 177 ; 20 L. Ed., 557; Wynehamer vs. People, 13 N. Y., 398; People vs. Otis, 90 N. Y., 48.'' There is an aspect of the effect of the clause upon the carrier's rights other than the mere question of deprivation of property itself (though inseparably connected with that aspect of the matter), and that is the interference with the right of the carrier to manage its own affairs. The idea is well illustrated by the language of Justice Jackson, then circuit judge, in the case of Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Balti- more & Ohio R. Co., 43 Fed., 37, which is adopted by the Supreme Court in C, N. 0. & T. P. R. Co. vs. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S., 184, 197 (and approved in Interstate Commerce Commission vs, Alabama Midland R. Co., 168 U. S., 144, 173, and other cases, including the late case of Interstate Com- merce Commission vs. Chicago, etc., R. Co., 209 U. S., 108, 119) : ^^ Subject to the two leading prohibitions that their charges shall not be unjust or un- reasonable, and that they shall not unjustly dis- 81 criminate, so as to give undue preference or dis- advantage to persons or traffic similarly circum- stanced, the Act to Regulate Commerce leaves common carriers as they were at the common law, free to make special contracts looking to the increase of their business, to classify their traffic, to adjust and apportion their rates so as to meet the necessities of commerce, and gen- erally to manage their important interests upon the same principles which are regarded as sound, and adopted in other trades and pur- suits.'^ The case of Lake Shore, etc., R. Co. vs. Smith, 173 U. S., 674, forcibly illustrates the principle. In that case a statute of Michigan requiring railroads to sell mileage books at a reduced rate was condemned by the Supreme Court as violating the Fourteenth Amend- ment. The principles upon which the case was decided will appear from the following quotation : **The legislature having established such maximum as a general law now assumes to interfere with the management of the company while conducting its affairs pursuant to and obeying the statute regulating rates and charges, and notwithstanding such rates it as- sumes to provide for a discrimination, an ex- ception in favor of those who may desire and are able to purchase tickets at what might be called wholesale rates — a discrimination which operates in favor of the wholesale buyer, leav- ing the others subject to the general rule. And it assumes to regulate the time in which the tickets purchased shall be valid and to lengthen it to double the period the railroad company has 6-E 82 ever before provided. It thus invades the gen- eral right of a company to conduct and manage its own affairs, and compels it to give the use of its property for less than the general rate to those who come within the provisions of the statute, and to that extent it would seem that the statute takes the property of the company without due process of law/' Again, p. 692: ^^The right to claim from the company trans- portation at reduced rates by purchasing a cer- tain amount of tickets is classed as a conven- ience. As so defined it would be more con- venient if the right could be claimed without any compensation whatever. But such a right is not a convenience at all within the meaning of the term as used in relation to the subject of furnishing conveniences to the public. And also the convenience which the legislature is to protect is not the convenience of a small por- tion only of the persons who may travel on the road, while refusing such alleged conven- ience to all others, nor is the right to obtain tickets for less than the general and otherwise lawful rate to be properly described as a con- venience. If that were true, the granting of the right to some portion of the public to ride free on all trains and at all times might be so de- scribed. What is covered by the word * con- venience' it might be difficult to define for all cases, but we think it does not cover this case. An opportunity to purchase a thousand-mile ticket for less than the standard rate we think is improperly described as a convenience." 83 Again (pp. 694-695) : **If the legislature can interfere by directing the sale of tickets at less than the generally es- tablished rate, it can compel the company to carry certain persons or classes free. If the maximum rates are too high in the judgment of the legislature, it may lower them, provided they do not make them unreasonably low as that term is understood in the law; but it cannot enact a law making maximum rates, and then proceed to make exceptions to it in favor of such persons or classes as in the legislative judgment or caprice may seem proper. What right has the legislature to take from the company the compensation it would otherwise receive for the use of its property in transporting an individual or classes of persons over its road, and compel them to transport them free or for a less sum than is provided for by the general law? Does not such an act, if enforced, take the property of the company without due process of law? We are convinced that the legislature cannot thus interfere with the conduct of the affairs of corporations.*' This case is followed in a dissenting opinion by three judges of the Kentucky Court of Appeals, in Louis- ville & Nashville R. Co. vs. Commonwealth, 51 S. W., supra, at page 1012, which is directly in point in con- nection with the question here to be determined. The court said (pp. 1012-1013) : ^* Under the law as construed by the majority opinion, the company must (1) increase its rates from the Kentucky mines to Louisville beyond the rates fixed to Lebanon, or (2) decrease the 84 rates from the mines to Lebanon below those charged to Louisville, or (3) depend upon the arbitrary will of the railroad commissioners to adjust the rates as to them may seem proper. If the first alternative is forced on the company, the result is a prohibition of the carriage of coal from the mines to Louisville, as none could be sold there. This result would be confessedly an unwarrantable interference with the reason- able use of the company's property. If the sec- ond, then the company is forced to furnish the use of its property at a price below that which is reasonable, and at rates below those which afford a fair and just return on the capital in- vested. This is true, because it is to be assumed that the rates from the mines to Lebanon are already reasonable and just. The proof offered is conclusive on this point. The only remaining refuge of the company is to submit its manage- ment to the arbitrary will of the commissioners. And this, say the court in effect, is better than to leave the matter at issue to a jury. I think the court overlooks the fact that a jury must act within the rules of law. A trial before a jury is had under the ordinary forms of law. The judge and jury are at least controlled and bound by legal principles and precedents. I think, in the first place, neither Congress nor the consti- tutional convention ever intended to vest their respective boards of commissioners with such extraordinary powers ; and, in the second place, I think the law so construed would result in an unwarrantable interference with the reasonable use of the appellants ' property, and to an extent not permissible under either State or Federal Constitution. ' ' In Piatt vs, Le Cocq, 150 Fed., 391, the Circuit Court for the District of South Dakota was called upon to construe a statute of South Dakota making it unlawful for any common carrier to give any preference to any person, locality, etc., or subject any kind of traffic to any disadvantage. The court interpreted the statute to refer to undue advantage and undue prejudice, say- ing (p. 397) : ^*The legislature could not have intended a literal enforcement of the statute, because that would leave the express company no discretion in the conduct of this business whatever, and, if the law could be construed as prohibiting any prejudice or disadvantage, the validity of the law would be in danger. ' ' In Interstate Commerce Commission vs. Chicago, etc., R. Co., 209 U. S., 108, where it was necessary for the court to determine whether the Interstate Com- merce Act permitted the carrier to make a lower rate for manufactured packing-house products than for live stock, the court said, Justice Brewer delivering the opinion (118-119) : '^It must be remembered that railroads are the private property of their owners ; that while from the public character of the work in which they are engaged the public has the power to prescribe rules for securing faithful and efficient service and equality between shippers and com- munities, yet in no proper sense is the public a general manager.'' In Chicago, etc., R. Co. vs. Chicago (C. C. N. D. 111.), 142 Fed., 844, a city ordinance requiring a street railroad to accept transfers issued by other companies 86 was condemned under the Fourteenth Amendment, Judge Grosscup saying : **The enjoyment of property meant by the 14th Amendment is that full exercise of domin- ion over one's own property — over that which one has himself created— that the whole law of property, from ancient times down to the pres- ent time, gives to a man, subject only to the par- amount rights of the State. * * * Domin- ion is enjoyment, and dominion is a part of the property right that the 14th Amendment was in- tended to protect.'* In Lawton vs, Steele, 152 U. S., 133, the court said: **The legislature may not, under the guise of protecting the public interests, arbitrarily inter- fere with private business, or impose unusual or unnecessary restrictions upon lawful occupa- tions." See Allgeyer vs, Louisiana, 165 U. S., 578, 589 ; Story on the Constitution, section 1950 ; 2 Tiedeman, Control of Persons and Property, p. 939. In Bonnett vs, Vallier, 17 L. E. A. (N. S.), 496, the court declared: ** While the police power is one whose proper use makes most potently for good, in its unde- fined scope and inordinate exercise lurks no small danger to the Republic. For the difficulty which is experienced in defining its just limits and bounds, affords a temptation to the legis- lature to encroach upon the rights of citizens with experimental laws, none the less dangerous because well meant." 87 In Wyatt vs. Ashbrook, 48 L. R. A., 265, the court said: **Mere legislative assumption of the right to direct and indicate the channel and course into which the private energies of the citizen shall flow, or the attempt to abridge or hamper his right to pursue any lawful calling or avocation which he may choose without unreasonable reg- ulation or molestation, have ever been con- demned in all free government." John K. Graves. January, 1911. 88 APPENDIX B. Extract from Address by Mr. W. W. Finley, President of Southern Rail- way Company, before the Traffic Club of Philadelphia, on February 18, 1911. About a month ago, in an address which I delivered before the Traffic Club, of Washington, D. C, I stated, what I had said on previous occasions, that **the only just method of determining the reasonableness of transportation charges is to measure them by the serv- ice performed." A newspaper, in commenting edito- rially on my address, said, in effect : ' ' This is all right as far as it goes, but will not Mr. Finley tell us just how to apply this yard-stick?" That is what I shall attempt to do this evening. In order to lay a broad and firm foundation, I shall first state some underlying facts and principles which I believe to be self-evident. At the outset, it should be borne in mind that the railways of the United States — although public high- ways, and, as such, properly subject to such govern- mental regulation as will insure to all citizens equality of rights on them, under similar circumstances and conditions, and as will prevent unreasonable or extor- tionate charges — have, nevertheless, been built with private capital and are the private property of their owners. It is a fundamental economic truth that the invest- ment of funds in any class of property is dependent on the safety of the principal and the rate of profit that may be expected as compared with the rate that can be 89 earned on investments in other kinds of business. In other words, the flow of capital into any particular business will be retarded unless it may be expected to earn a reasonable profit as compared with the earn- ings of capital in other enterprises. The wise men who framed the Constitution of the United States took cognizance of this principle when they threw the pro- tection of that supreme law of our land about private property in language which the profound lawyers who have composed our Supreme Court have held to cover not only the property itself but the right to its profit- able use. Thus, as the Supreme Court said, in the case of Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul R. R. Co. vs, Minnesota : **If the company is deprived of the power of charging reasonable rates for the use of its property, and such deprivation takes place in the absence of investigation by judicial ma- chinery, it is deprived of the lawful use of its property, and thus, in substance and effect, of the property itself, without due process of law and in violation of the Constitution of the United States; and in so far as it is thus de- prived, while other persons are permitted to re- ceive reasonable profits upon their invested capital, the company is deprived of the equal protection of the laws.'' ' Thus the constitutional standard and the economic standard for the fixing of a charge for any specific service by a privately owned railway are the same. It must be reasonable, as measured by the service per- formed. It is the common-law rule that he who per- forms service, in the absence of a specific contract, is entitled to just compensation for that service, and it is 90 this rule which has governed the courts of England for centuries, and of our own country from colonial times, in determining all controversies as to prices of commodities and charges for services. The United States Interstate Commerce Law pro- vides that ^*all charges made for any service rendered or to be rendered in the transportation of passengers or property * * * shall be just and reasonable/* This is simply the legislative enactment of the consti- tutional and economic standard to which I have re- ferred. The standard is thus clearly established. It is the right of the carrier to receive reasonable compensa- tion for each service, as measured by that service. That the application of this standard, in specific in- stances, may be difficult does not excuse failure to ap- ply it. It is being applied with more or less exactness in the practical every-day fixing of charges by the railways and in the cases before the Interstate Com- merce Commission and the courts involving the rea- sonableness of specific charges. The question of what is a reasonable charge for a specific service is complicated by the fact that neither, as a matter of transportation policy or of public policy, can charges on all classes of traffic be uniform. Com- modities of great weight or bulk in proportion to their value must be carried at rates substantially lower than those which may properly be charged for the carriage of commodities which are of high value in proportion to their weight or bulk. As a result of the necessity for different rates on different classes of commodities, each individual rate or each rate applying to a class of commodities must be considered on its merits in its relation to the par- ticular service performed. The cost of performing the service, as nearly as it can be ascertained, must cer- 91 tainly be taken into consideration. No rate should be made so low as not to pay something more than what Mr. Acworth, the eminent English economist, has aptly termed 'Hhe actual out-of-pocket cosf of mov- ing that particular traffic. If it pays this cost and con- tributes, even in small measure, toward the general ex- penses and fixed charges of the carrier, it is a profit- able rate, provided the carrier has a considerable vol- ume of traffic moving at higher rates. The low-class traffic moved at these low rates is not a burden on the higher-class traffic, for, by just so much as it contrib- utes to general expenses and fixed charges, it reduces the amount which the higher-class traffic must con- tribute. In practical rate-making the question of the cost of the service has a controlling bearing only as determining the level below which a rate cannot prop- erly be made. The value of the service is another important factor in rate-making and in determining the reasonableness of a rate that may be challenged. Transportation en- ables those engaged in any given industry to carry on their business in those localities best suited for it and to market elsewhere the surplus not needed for con- sumption at the point of production. By moving com- modities from places where the supply exceeds the local demand to places where they are scarce and are wanted, additional value is given to the whole volume of production — including the proportion consumed lo- cally, as well as to that carried to other markets. As affecting the consumer of — let us say, cotton goods, by way of illustration — the carriage of the raw cotton to the mill and the transportation of the finished goods to his market, is a process of production. This trans- portation gives added value to the raw cotton produced on the farm, and to the goods produced in the cotton mill, and the carrier is, therefore, entitled to fair rec- 92 ognition for its service in the process of producing the finished cloth and placing it in the hands of consumers, just the same as is the farmer and the cotton-mill owner. The increased value given to a commodity by trans- portation is the measure of the value of the service to the owner of the commodity. It is not, however, the absolute measure of a reasonable rate, for, if the trans- portation charges were so high as to absorb all of this increased value, the owner would have no incentive to ship and the traffic would not move. This may be il- lustrated by referring to the rail movement of a very low-grade commodity, such as ordinary sand — a com- modity which is found in abundance in most localities and the value of which, generally speaking, can be very little increased by transportation. It is manifest that it would be impossible to make a practical rate on sand for any such distance as from Philadelphia to Chi- cago, for the reason that the out-of-pocket cost of per- forming the service would be far in excess of the value of the service to the shipper. As transportation has contributed all of the in- creased value which is given a commodity by its car- riage to market, which, as we have seen, is a factor in effective production, the carrier is entitled to a reason- able share of that increase. The value of the service is, therefore, a most important factor in determining what is a reasonable charge for a specific transaction. Out of the intimate relation of the cost of the service and the value of the service to the reasonableness of a transportation charge grows the fact that, in an era of generally advancing prices, when both the cost of the service and the value of the service are increasing, the level of the reasonable charge for the service thus af- fected also advances. 93 In determining the proportion of the value of the service which the carrier may reasonably and justly charge for its part in creating that value, intelligent consideration must be given to comparison with rates charged by the carrier for other similar services, to comparison with the rates of competing carriers, to comparison with the rates at which carriers in other localities move the same commodity under similar cir- cumstances and conditions, to comparison with the rates on similar commodities which might be substituted in use for the one in question, to the intrinsic value of the commodity, to the risk of breakage or other injury in transit, to the insurance risk, to the effect of the rate on the volume of traffic, and to the general condition of the business to which the special traffic is related. When the reasonableness of a rate is called into ques-* tion, consideration and great weight must be given to expert testimony. Of all these guides for determining the reasonable- ness of a specific rate, the effect on traffic is perhaps the most important, for an increasing volume of traffic is prima facie, and almost conclusive, evidence that the rate is not unreasonably high, though it may be un- reasonably low. It will be seen that, in the final analysis, the reason- ableness of a transportation charge is largely a mat- ter of expert judgment. So is the reasonableness of any price or charge that may be called into question. If one of you employs a lawyer, without any agreement as to what his fee shall be, and, after the service has been performed, you decline to pay his bill on the ground that it is too high, he sues you for the amount of his bill. The question raised is what would consti- tute a reasonable charge for the service performed, and, on this, testimony will be introduced to show, pri- marily and principally, the value of the service to you. 94 Testimony will also be presented as to the usual fees which this lawyer and other lawyers receive for sim- ilar services, as to the amount of time consumed, and the skill which he displayed in rendering the service. Based on this testimony the jury will form a judgment as to what is a reasonable charge for the specific serv- ice performed. The same method is followed in con- demnation proceedings when a railway company seeks to acquire land for railway purposes and fails to reach an agreement with the owner as to the price to be paid. The question here presented is as to the fair and rea- sonable present value of the land to its owner and as to the fair and reasonable amount to be allowed him for the damage, if any, that may result to his remaining property by the construction of a railway through it. Evidence will be considered as to the value of that par- ticular strip of land, as to the profitableness of the uses to which it has been put by its owner or of the uses to which it might be put. Evidence will also be considered as to the prices at which other tracts of land in the same locality have been sold, and on all these points expert testimony will be considered. The amount which the owner paid for the land, if bought sufficiently near the time of condemnation to be perti- nent, may be introduced in evidence and will be con- sidered, but it is not controlling on the jury, which, from all the evidence introduced, must determine what is the just and reasonable compensation to its owner at the particular time when it is taken. You will note that I have said nothing as to the cost of a railway, its value, or its capitalization as factors in determining the reasonableness of any specific transportation charge. The reason is that, while it is essential to the continued development of the railway system of the United States that the whole body of charges shall be such as to yield such profits as will 95 attract capital to investment in railway enterprises, neither cost, value, nor capitalization can have any controlling bearing on the reasonableness of any par- ticular charge for a specific service by any particular railway. Every railway traffic official strives to obtain such an adjustment of each charge for a specific service as will result in the total charges for all services rendered by his company yielding a maximum of revenue. When he comes to the fixing of any specific charge, however, he finds that his discretion is limited very narrowly by economic forces entirely beyond his con- trol. He must consider the competition of other car- riers. He must consider the competition of producers in localities off of the line of his road who are market- ing the same commodity in the same markets as the producers on his road. He must consider the compe- tition of markets which are seeking to draw com- modities produced along his line away from the mark- kets which it serves. He must consider the competi- tion of similar commodities which may possibly be used in substitution for the one affected by the specific charge under consideration. These competitive forces, and the necessity for so adjusting the charge as to en- courage the movement of traffic, effectively fix a level above which he is powerless to advance the charge. He cannot give practical consideration to either the cost of the railway, its value, or its capitalization. If it were otherwise, and if, as seems to be believed in some quarters, transportation charges could be so ad- justed as to yield a certain return on railway capital, every railway would be profitable to its owners and such a thing as a bankrupt railway company would be unknown, unless caused by dishonesty or mismanage- ment. 96 Transportation charges being controlled so largely by the competitive forces to which I have referred and by the necessity of keeping each charge below the max- imum of the value of the service in order to insure the movement of traffic, it follows that the intelligent railway manager, having in view the ultimate inter- ests of the property intrusted to his care, will seek so to adjust each specific charge that it will be reasonable as measured by the specific service. If, through faulty judgment or for any other cause, he shall err in the fixing of any specific charge, his error may be corrected by the machinery which the law has provided for the correction of any charge that may be unreason- able as measured by this standard. When the specific charges of a railway company have been so adjusted that each is reasonable, as measured by the service performed, and when that company ab- stains from any undue discrimination in charges or service between individuals, localities, or commodities, if, by reason of the poor location of the railway, high cost of construction, faulty management, or any other cause, the revenues derived from all of its charges are so small as to yield no net return on its capitaliza- tion, that is the misfortune of its owners. On the other hand, if, by reason of the favorable location of the road, low cost of construction, efficiency of manage- ment, or any other cause, the net return to the owners of the property is substantial, that is their good for- tune. They are entitled to the use and enjoyment of the whole of such net returns in the same measure as the farmer whose land is fertile and is favorably lo- cated is entitled to the use and enjoyment of all that he can make out of his farm by the most efficient man- agement. The reciprocal obligations of the railways and the people were clearly stated by Senator Bailey, of Texas, 97 in an address dealing with this subject delivered be- fore the New York State Bar Association on January 20, 1910, in which he said : **The obligation of every railroad to the peo- ple is to render them a prompt, safe, and proper service; and to render every person the same service for the same pay. The obligation of the people to every railroad is to pay a just com- pensation for such services as they require of it ; and the whole duty, as well as the whole power of the Government, begins and ends with the due enforcement of these reciprocal obliga- tions." Senator Bailey thus clearly defines the limit of the duty and the power of government in the regulation of railways built and operated by private capital. His clear and logical mind rejects as legally and econom- ically unsound the measuring of the reasonableness of a transportation charge by any other standard than that of just compensation for the service performed. In the same address he exposes the legal fallacy and the practical impossibility of considering the value of railway property as a controlling factor in determin- ing the reasonableness of a charge for transportation service. While it was not a case involving railway rates, I believe that the views announced by Justice Brewer of the Supreme Court in Cotting vs. Kansas City Stock Yards Company lay down in clear and unmis- takable language the rule which should be applied to the determination of the reasonableness of any rail- way charge. Speaking of a person who has devoted his property to a public use, Justice Brewer said : 7~E 98 '^The State's regulation of his charges is not to be measured by the aggregate of his profits, determined by the volume of business, but by the question whether any particular charge to an individual dealing with him is, considering the service rendered, an unreasonable exaction. In other words, if he has a thousand transac- tions a day, and his charges in each are but a reasonable compensation for the benefit re- ceived by the party dealing with him, such charges do not become unreasonable because, by reason of the multitude, the aggregate of his profits is large. The question is not how much he makes out of his volume of business, but whether in each particular transaction the charge is an unreasonable exaction for the serv- ices rendered. He has a right to do business. He has a right to charge for each separate serv- ice that which is reasonable compensation there- for, and the legislature may not deny him such reasonable compensation, and may not interfere simply because, out of the multitude of his transactions, the amount of his profits is large." In this cas^ Justice Brewer clearly announces the rule which I believe should be applied to all questions affecting the reasonableness of railway charges. He clearly lays down the principle that the only question involved in the matter there under discussion was whether any particular charge for a specific service was an unreasonable exaction as measured by that serv- ice. He indicates that the value of the service to the person for whom it is rendered must be the principal factor in determining the reasonableness of the charge. This rule eliminates from consideration, except as I shall hereafter explain, all questions of capitalization 99 and of the value or cost of the property used in per- forming the service by declaring explicitly that *'the legislature may not deny him such reasonable compen- sation, and may not interfere simply because, out of the multitude of his transactions, the amount of his profits is large/' The application of this rule to pri- vately owned railways, which I believe to be proper and will ultimately be done, clearly denies to govern- ment the right to place any limitation on the amount that may be earned on railway capital. It would in- vite the people of the United States to invest their money in the great and honorable business of trans- portation with the assurance that the properties they create will have the equal protection of the laws and will be surrounded by the same safeguards as are thrown around property in other forms. It would en- courage those engaged in this business to strive con- stantly to make their service more efficient by the adoption of improved appliances and methods, with the assurance that they will be permitted to reap the profits of their enterprise and skill. While it is an economic and practical impossibility so to adjust any charge for a specific transportation service that it shall bear a fixed and predetermined re- lation to railway value or capitalization, there are cer- tain conditions under which the return on the capital invested must be considered in determining questions as to the reasonableness of charges. I believe I have established the proposition that when the charges of a railway are not exorbitant or unreasonably high, as measured by the service performed, 'the right to pos- sess and enjoy the profits it may earn, be they much or little, is a property right in which its owners are pro- tected by the Constitution of the United States. It follows that, unless it can be- clearly established that the charges of a railway are exorbitant and unreasonably 100 high, as measured by the standard of service, any re- duction attempted to be made by governmental author- ity is an unconstitutional act, and evidence showing that such reduction would deprive the owners of the property of a reasonable return on their investment would be conclusive as to its unconstitutionality. Fur- ther, in a time of advancing commodity prices and labor costs, the fact that the whole body of its trans- portation charges fails to yield a fair and reasonable return on the capital invested in a railway is pre- sumptive evidence that there has been such an increase in the cost of the service and in the value of the serv- ice as to require a readjustment of charges upon a higher average level. This is but another way of say- ing that rates must be reasonable for, and under the conditions and circumstances of, the service. In the changed conditions growing out of higher prices for everything else a higher price for railway transporta- tion becomes reasonable. Under such conditions it is to the public interest that such a readjustment should take place, for the primary interest of the public in the railways is in adequacy of facilities and efficiency of service, and these can be provided, in a country with a constantly increasing volume of traffic, only when the average re- turn on capital invested in railways bears such a rela- tion to the returns on investments in other forms of property as to insure a constant flow of new capital into railway enterprises. In other words, the fair maintenance of the just credit of the railways is a cir- cumstance which, should be taken into consideration in determining the reasonableness of rates, not only in the interest of the railways, but in the interest of the public. In this connection, I think we may properly refer to the relation of the governmental policy of Ger- many to the wonderful industrial development that has • • ••. .* • •• . 101 marked the recent history of that country and is still in progress. It is not without significance that we find the highest court in the German Empire saying : ''When in a branch of industry the prices of a product fall too low, and the successful con- duct of the industry is endangered or becomes impossible, the crisis which sets in is detri- mental, not merely to individuals, but to soci- ety as a whole. It is in the interests of the com- munity, therefore, that inordinately low prices should not exist in any industry for a long time." If this is true as to the prices of the products of any industry, Mr. Toastmaster, I believe it is equally true of the charges of a railway, for transportation is a part of production, and, in our modern civilization, the prosperity of every industry and of every individual is affected, directly or indirectly, by transportation. The desire of each man to better his condition and to provide for his family is the mainspring of human progress. I believe that each man should have the most ample liberty to achieve success consistent with the preservation of the same degree of liberty to all other men. I do not believe that, as to those of our fellow-citizens engaged in the business of transporta- tion or any other lawful calling, the intelligent public opinion of the United States will return an affirmative answer to the question which Justice Brewer asked in the Cotting case, to which I have referred, as follows : ' ' Is it true in this country that one who, by at- tention to business, by his efforts to satisfy cus- tomers, by his sagacity in discerning the prob- able courses of trade, and by contributing of his 102 means to bring trade into those lines, succeeds in building up a large and profitable business, becomes thereby a legitimate object of the legis- lative scalping knifeT' I believe, Mr. Toastmaster, that the preservation of individual liberty is essential to our progress as a peo- ple, and that the millions of Americans, each seeking to preserve the most ample opportunities for himself and his children, would look upon it as a national calamity if we should say to any citizen ^'that his in- dustry, ability, activity, and foresight may be re- warded up to a certain extent and that beyond that he may not go. ' ' [10609J TJNIVEESITT OF CALIFOBNIA LIBEAET, BEEKEIiET THIS BOOK IS DT]^ THE LAST DATE THIS BOO g^^^j^jjj, 3EL0W Books not return^ on 'jme .t. -Jj|t Vcreasing 50c per 'o'ttme,"""" ',?^-7ie .irth day. Books not in °IS?atioa of lo»n period. = AUG J^ \m 20rn-ll,'20 V MAKERS SVRAGUSF,- tfV. 257194 ^m%