GIFT ! 39 1914 Workmen's Compensation and Insurance in France, Holland and Switzerland A Series of Letters by Harold G. Villard Revised and Reprinted January, J9J4 Workmen's Compensation and Insurance in France, Holland and Switzerland A Series of Letters t>7 Harold G. Villard Revised and Reprinted January, J9J4 The following letters, written from various points in Europe, be- tween July, 1912, and June, 1913, contain the results of studies of the practical operations of the French, Dutch and Swiss workmen's in- surance laws, besides a brief discussion of the recent Swiss legislation, which is not yet in effect. No attempt is made at a complete analysis of the various statutes discussed. For that information the reader should consult the Reports and Bulletins of the United States Bureau of Labor. In this reprint a number of corrections and of additions to the statis- tical data have been made. HAROLD G. VILLARD. 205 West 57th Street, New York. December, 1913. 678980 CONTENTS. French Accident Compensation Law: Page. Experience thereunder Principles and Objects of the Law Misconstruction Growing Abuses 7 Insurance thereunder Self, State, Co-operative and Corporate Insurance State Insurance not in favor Showing of Pri- vate Companies State Monopoly Idea 15 Principal Abuses thereunder Increased Cost Litigation over and Pensions for Trifling Injuries Medical Abuses 23 French Sickness Insurance Law: Voluntary Mutual Associations Government Subsidies Recent Progress and Growing Importance Defects 33 French Old Age Pension Law: Reasons for its Non-Success and Unpopularity 39 Dutch Accident Compensation Insurance Law: How Compensation Insured Functions performed by the State Extent of Abuses Some Defects ..." 42 State versus Private Insurance Higher Cost and Disadvan- tages of Former Disappearance of Self Insurance, Eclipse of Corporate Insurance and Rise of Mutual Insurance .... 48 Dutch Experience in Agricultural Accident Insurance: Voluntary In Mutual Associations Favorable Experience ... 60 Recent Swiss Workmen's Insurance Legislation: Good and Weak Points of the Measure Peculiar and Novel Features, and Reasons therefor The Sickness Insurance Law The Accident Insurance Law 63 Swiss Experience in Military Insurance: An Instructive Ten Year Test of State Insurance Unfavorable Experience 78 FRANCE Experience Under the Workmen's Accident Compensation Law.* Prin- ciples and Objects of the Law. Misconstructions. Grow- ing Abuses. Following the example set by Germany in 1884, practically all the leading industrial nations of Europe have, since then, passed laws af- fecting the compulsory insurance of workmen against accidents arising in the course of their employment. As is well known, this form of legislation has all been based on the same general theory of partial reparation and of a division of the loss arising from the accidents be- tween masters and workmen. Instead of employers being liable, as heretofore, only in cases where negligence could be imputed to them, they are obliged to indemnify victims of accidents in all cases. On the other hand, employees injured through no fault of their own re- ceive, not full, but only partial, compensation, while those at fault have their loss in earnings made partially good, instead of receiving no redress from their patrons, as was the previous custom. In every case, workmen are to forego full compensation, and in no instance are employers to be mulcted to the full extent of their previ- ous liability. To relieve the laborer from all loss or penalty in case of accidents, one-half of all of which are usually due to his negligence, would throw an unfair burden on the employer, and would tend to de- moralize the workman by making him indifferent or careless. In order to prevent the simulation of accidents, and to make the victims anxious for their hurts to heal quickly, an employee should never be allowed to turn an injury into a source of profit. The accident-insurance statutes were, therefore, purposely intended to be only partially repara- tive, and were not meant to be a means of bestowing alms or charity on any one. What the Object Is. In discussing this class of legislation, another fact should be borne in mind, namely, that its object is not to make amends for the mutila- tion or disfigurement of the human body, but merely to compensate in *Reprinted from New York Evening Post of March 29, 1913, by per- mission. part for any reduction in wages resulting from that loss. A victim may be terribly seared and scarred, but he is not entitled to receive any satisfaction for the loss of his good looks, unless accompanied by a diminution in his wage-earning capacity. No sentimental reasons, but purely business principles, should be applied in the interpretation of accident insurance statutes. The probable salary after, as compared wi'r-h: that; aretl before the occurrence of the injury, should be the basis oh- wHitrh" any compenoation is to be estimated. In the considera- tion of French or any other legislation on accident insurance, these general rules or observations should be kept in mind. When the French statute was passed in 1898, its sponsors clearly understood that it was based on the idea of give and take. As one Senator defined it: "The law is in the nature of a bargain; for, if it obliges the head of an industrial undertaking to make good the loss in- curred by the victim, without inquiry as to the cause of the accident, on the other hand, it only makes the patron responsible for a part of the damage suffered." Unfortunately this original basis of the law has been more and more lost sight of, and the tendency is to construe and amend the act as though intended to make the employers the ones to be held re- sponsible for any damages resulting from accidents. Disregarding the fact that the employees were to share the burden, too, both courts and legislature are daily more inclined to interpret and to change the law so as to aid the injured as much as possible in their efforts to obtain compensation from their superiors. The statute has come to Joe re- garded more as a species of class legislation and as a measure directed against the employers in the interests of the workingmen. Hence the feeling that the poor and unfortunate should be favored whenever pos- sible in their attempts to recover from the well-to-do masters and that the employees and physicians are acting quite legitimately and entirely within their rights in endeavoring to turn the law into as great a source of pecuniary profit to themselves as possible. Other Grave Evils. Besides becoming thereby a socialistic instrument of oppression, this narrow construction of the law has entailed other grave evils. The laborer no longer looks upon an injury solely as a great misfortune; his principal thought now is how, by exaggeration or otherwise, to make his hurts produce for him the largest monetary return. Forgetting the place assigned to him of impartial arbiter between conflicting interests, the physician has assumed the law to have been enacted for his pecu- niary benefit, too, and feels justified in swelling his charges for treat- ment to the maximum possible amount, basing his attentions more ac- cording to the size of the employer's purse than to the victim's station in life. Lastly, the reform of the law and the doing away with abuses has become very difficult, because the radical socialistic majority in the Chamber of Deputies is disinclined to adopt any amendment urged 8 by employers, fearing that it may in some measure interfere with or curtail the rights or privileges of the workingmen. Indeed, the ten- dency is all the other way to let down the barriers still further and to facilitate the mulcting and exploitation of the employing class. Passing now to the interpretation of the law in French courts, com- pensation in cases resulting in permanent partial disability is fre- quently erroneously based on the bodily injury received. A workman in a textile industry, we will say, meets with an accident entailing the loss of the forefinger of his right hand. When the wound is healed, the attending physician certifies that the victim is suffering from a permanent injury which can never change or improve. On this state- ment, the Court issues a decree naming the sum the workman is to re- ceive. Now, while the loss of the finger was susceptible of reducing the workman's earnings, he might yet in time have been able so to train his other fingers that the output of his machine would be as great as before, and to earn the same salary as he originally obtained, in which event, of course, he should cease to receive any payment on account of his injury. By being governed by the bodily state of the victim by making the law a sort of pretium doloris and in overlooking the chance of the injured party's regaining some of his accustomed skill through train- ing other members to do the work of the missing part, the French courts are putting a much heavier burden in the shape of compensation for permanent injuries on French industrial heads than is the case in other countries. In Germany, for example, the mutilation of the work- man is disregarded. His loss in earning power is the sole criterion of compensation as his wages rise, the latter diminishes or ceases al- together. \ Rulings in Minor Accidents. In the matter of minor accidents involving a disability of 10 per cent or less, the rulings of the highest court is again placing the French employers at a disadvantage, as compared with other competitors. In Germany no compensation is granted in such cases and some of the lower French courts have followed the same policy up to a 5 per cent limit. Within a few months, however, the court of the highest jurisdic- tion has decided that the law directs the payment of an indemnity in all cases where the disability incurred is susceptible of causing, under normal conditions, a reduction in the victim's earning capacity, and that it fixes no minimum below which an indemnity is not allowed. The practice of refusing compensation in accidents of minimum im- portance on the ground that the injury received is not susceptible of causing any appreciable reduction in the injured party's earning power is condemned and held to be erroneous. This ruling of the Cour de Cassation appears very unfortunate for many reasons. It construes the law from a narrow point of view and leaves out of account the theory of reparation and the broader pur- 9 pose of the statute. Instead of holding that in cases of inappreciable injury and of small fractional reduction in wages no indemnity is due, the court preferred the view that every hurt, irrespective of size or gravity, must be compensated for. Not the question of monetary loss, but the occurrence of an injury is to entitle the workman to damages. Now the fact is that in the vast majority of minor accident cases, the workman cannot show any reduction in salary in consequence thereof. Suppose him to earn fifty cents a day, and to lose 4 per cent of his former efficiency he will not be put in a class by himself at 48 cents, but will continue to draw his full pay as before. To pay the slightly injured laborer under these circumstances is to bestow an undeserved gratuity on him and to encourage him to nurse and magnify the smallest contusions which were unnoticed before. The law is twisted from its original intention and becomes a source of profit to the workman with an insignificant wound. This regrettable interpretation is certainly bound to increase the number of claims for petty accidents, which were excessive enough be- fore. In 1906, almost 60 per cent of the accident cases settled in the courts related to permanent disability of 10 per cent or less, which in Germany would have been regarded as too unimportant to be worthy of redress. While mulcting the employers, this insistence on compensa- tion in minor accident cases has heretofore proven to be of little ulti- mate benefit to the workmen themselves. Settlement is usually made by paying the victim a lump sum, which he is only too apt to waste, in- stead of applying his award to a good purpose. Attention has already been called to the difficulty of securing any legislation against abuses in the French accident insurance law. The proposals of the employers are regarded with suspicion and only one of the amendments recommended by them has been adopted by the ap- propriate committee of the Chamber of Deputies. All the changes op- posed by them have been almost uniformly adopted, and some will un- doubtedly be finally enacted into law. Crying Evils of French Law. Unquestionably, the most crying evils in the French law are due to the clause giving the injured workman the right to select his own physician and pharmacist. Without going into the subject at length, it is sufficient to say that, owing to an unholy alliance beween the physicians and the laborers, the employers are exploited and fleeced at every turn. False medical certificates, undue prolongation of and unnecessarily expensive treatments, simulation of injuries, all these and other dishonest practices are resorted to. So profitable has this sort of practice become that many doctors in Paris actually pay the patients who present themselves for treatment. The customary rate is five francs for the first call and thereafter a daily stipend not to exceed two francs until a cure is effected. In the end the employers have to make good these improper outlays in one shape or another. 10 Physicians will at their own expense fit up clinics for the handling of accident cases among trade-unionists, and rebate to the union with which they are affiliated from 25 to 50 per cent of the fees collected. Under the system of free choice, the workman suffers in that when injured he seeks the practitioner who will pay him the largest retaining fee instead of the one most skilled, who will cure him in the shortest possible time. The employer loses through being swindled and over- charged. In the face of such patent abuses, common sense would indicate that the most efficacious remedy would be to have only the employers name the physicians in accident cases so that those who have to meet the medical costs should have the means of controlling them. No harm could come to the workingman for it is in the master's interest too that any one injured be restored to health in as brief a period as possible. But the French legislator is too timid to follow any such course, or to restrict the laborer's liberty or freedom of choice in any respect. Instead, a sort of half-way measure is finding favor and stands the best chance of enactment, which calls for the appointment of two physicians in all accident cases one to represent each side. Ex- perience alone would show how far this change would affect the pres- ent abuses and whether it would reduce the item of medical costs ap- preciably or not. Restricting the choice of physicians to the employers would be a much more direct and efficacious way of controlling and getting rid of the now existing evils. How the law is losing its character of a partially reparative meas- ure, where both masters and men are called upon to share the loss, is illustrated again in the change already made and further proposed re- garding the period which must elapse before the injured workman re- ceives compensation. In the original act, this time was fixed at four days, the idea being that, as a necessary check on simulation of acci- dents, the laborer should stand the loss for this initial period. A new distinction was made in 1905, however, when a clause was inserted pro- viding that an indemnity was due from the first day on in cases where the length of disability exceeded ten days. Effect of New Indemnity Clause. It does not require much calculation to foresee that this change was bound to encourage simulation, and to result in a decided augmentation of accidents purporting to have caused disability in excess of ten days. If a slightly injured laborer resumed work on the fifth day he would (allowing for a Sunday) have earned at the end of the eleventh day six days' full pay. By claiming continued disability, however, he would, under the law, be entitled to half pay for eleven days, or five and one- half full days' pay, or practically the same amount he would gain by working. Consequently, the workman is under every stimulus to ex- aggerate the extent of his hurts, and not to resume work until eleven days or more have expired. That the alteration in the law has had 11 -f -f -f -f- this very effect is strikingly proved by the following table of the length of disability in accidents settled by a certain group of French insur- ance companies in the year just before and in the year directly after the change in the law was made: Number of Accidents. Days Difference. disabled. 1904. 1906. Per cent. 5 .................................. 1,753 2,196 -f 25 6 .................................. 2,448 2,931 + 20 7 ................................ ' . . 2,697 2,063 - 23 8 .................................. 2,965 2,439 - 18 9 .................................. 3,132 2,479 - 21 10 .................................. 3,095 3,570 + 15 11 .................................. 3,037 6,799 12 .................................. 2,909 6,625 13 .................................. 2,866 5,850 14 .................................. 2,814 4,216 15 .................................. 2,802 4,837 16 to 20 ............................ 9,051 14,151 21 to 30 ............................ 8,349 12,443 31 to 40 ............................ 3,586 5,471 41 to 50 ............................ 1,771 2,560 51 to 60 ............................ 977 1,399 61 to 70 ....... . .................... 676 854 Over 70 ............................ 1,533 2,019 50,461 82,902 + 47 Total No. of accidents not over ten days 16,090 15,678 3 Of total number accidents (p.c.) ...... 32 19 - 13 Over 10 days ........................ 32,853 67,224 -f 96 Although the total number of accidents increased 47 per cent in the two years, those entailing disabilities of ten days or less actually showed a decrease. Instead of forming almost one-third of all accidents, they constitute less than one-fifth. The most striking feature in this table is, of course, the abnormal increase in accidents causing a cessation of work of from eleven to thirteen days. Employers Desire Repeal. As this amendment to the law has simply resulted in grave abuses and encourages the workman to simulate the extent of his injuries and to prolong his period of idleness, the employers have asked for its re- peal. Far from their wish being granted, the committee of the Cham- ber has just voted that the workmen's compensation shall run in all -f 123 -4-128 -f 104 -f 50 -f 73 56 49 53 45 -f 43 +26 -f 32 12 cases, irrespective of the length, of disability, from the first day. In- stead of remedying a flagrant abuse of the law, they would facilitate its generalization. Even in the French Mutual Aid societies, where a close inspectorship is maintained and self-interest impels the members to keep tab on one another, it has been found necessary, in order to guard against shamming, to refuse any sick or other benefits for the first two days. If no limit is imposed in accident cases, what way of preventing a dishonest employee from feigning a petty accident in order to enjoy a brief holiday on half pay? If all barriers are removed, the present heavy charges imposed on the employers will be increased at least 25 per cent, even if the number of accidents remains the same as now and without taking into account any possible increase through dishonest practices on the part of the workmen. Losing sight of the forfeitary principle on which the law was enacted, the committee have frankly stated that, in their opinion, the four days' provision gave the masters an unfair advantage, which they desired to see done away with as in- equitable. Again we find the erroneous conception that the law is in- tended solely to ameliorate the condition of the laboring class and that only the employers are to be called upon for sacrifices. If the removal of the four-day limit will put a premium on fraudu- lent practices and simulation, the same is true of another measure favored by the committee, providing that in case the victim's injury be- comes worse or aggravated, the payment of the indemnity allotted when the wound was declared healed, shall be suspended. So long as the new period of treatment lasts, the injured party is to draw again instead his half-pay, and all medical and pharmaceutical expenses are to be charged to the employer. The objection to this proposed amend- ment is, of course, that it makes any permanent settlement difficult, especially in cases of minor accidents. If the victim with a small award becomes sick or is thrown out of work, how great then the temp- tation to claim a relapse with the help of some dishonest physician and to draw half-pay until employment is again to be had. In times of trade depression the demands for a revision of indemnity would foe especially numerous. Where Heirs Profit by Death. Where death occurs, the accident insurance law, as revised in 1905. grants in certain cases indemnity to such of the victim's ascendants as can show that they were dependent on him for support. The com- mittee has, however, just voted to do away with this requirement, in which event the heirs of the victim would, in cases where they had not previously received any of the earnings, actually profit by his death. The basis of the present law the idea of partial reparation for an actual money loss suffered is again entirely lost sight of. On what theory except that it is a statute for the relief of the poor, should an employer of a workman who has died from an accident, be compelled 13 to contribute to the support of his relatives, to whom the laborer while alive never gave any part of his wages? But there is no need of giving any further instances. In brief, it may be said that all the evils against which an ideal law on the sub- ject of accident insurance should guard, are to be found in France to- day. Instead of being eradicated, abuses are being strengthened and multiplied. The burden on French industry is steadily mounting, and bids fair to be radically increased in the near future. At the same time the demoralization of employees goes on apace. It is no wonder, therefore that the leaders of industry look forward with grave ap- prehension as to what the future has in store for them as regards the compulsory insurance of their laborers against accidents. The history and application of the French act as well as past and prospective changes, all emphasize the necessity, in the interpretation of accident insurance statutes, of keeping clearly in mind the under- lying principles on which this form of legislation was originally based. Once the idea of a just and equitable division of an unavoidable indus- trial loss between masters and workmen is lost sight of, the inevitable tendency arises to construe the law as a piece of class legislation di- rected against the employers on whose shoulders the burden must be placed wherever possible. If the mere fact of injury and not the actual wage loss suffered be taken as the ground for compensation, the workman obtains a false conception of the purpose of the law and seeks, by resorting to simulation and exaggeration of injuries, to de- rive a profit from it. The ratification of abuses becomes increasingly difficult because the laborer resists any projected legislation which would take away any previously secured advantages, even if improperly obtained. Lastly, where a wrongful interpretation prevails, the danger is constantly present that the law will be turned more and more into a sort of poor relief measure at the employer's expense with the conse- quent disappearance of the idea of an equitable contribution by the workingmen. INSURANCE UNDER THE FRENCH ACCIDENT COMPENSATION LAW.* Self, State, Co-operative and Corporate Insurance. Employer's Op- tions. State Insurance Not in Favor. Showing of Private Companies. State Monopoly Idea. With the passage in 1898 of the law making the insurance of work- men against the risks of their employment compulsory, employers' liability insurance in France first began to develop on an important scale. The statute leaves entire liberty of action to the employer. He can either be his own insurer or have himself insured directly by the State, or by one of the various private organizations authorized by the Government to underwrite employer's risks. A large number of em- ployers, with nearly one-third of all the workmen affected by the law in their pay, have preferred not to take out any outside insurance, but to meet their own accident losses as they occur. As five out of every thousand employers, it is estimated, will fail to meet their workmen's liability insurance, the Government compels all employers to contribute to a special guarantee fund to make good losses incurred involving death or permanent disability to employees. If the trade is one requir- ing a license, this contribution was originally fixed at 4 per cent of the license tax; if not, the contribution became 2 per cent of the total premium paid for insurance. If the employer was uninsured, he had to pay in 4 per cent of the face value of all accident losses incurred by him, as they arose. With the exception of 1903, the guarantee fund has yielded each year a surplus, the total of which reached 12,241,892 fr. at the end of 1911. In view of this comparatively large surplus, the annual contributions are to be determined hereafter on a sliding scale based on the losses which the fund was called upon to make good during the year im- mediately previous, but in no case are they to exceed the figures orig- inally fixed. For the years 1906-11, the only years for which full statistics are available, the operation of this guarantee fund shows the following results: Receipts 15,692,465.34 Expenses and losses 8,171,704.05 Losses 5,712,654.65 Account insured employers 2,151,801.87 Account uninsured employers 3,560,852.78 Recovered from employers 2,201,511.71 Recovered from insured employers 1,970,166.37 Recovered from uninsured employers 231,345.67 Net losses account insured employers 181,645.50 Net losses account uninsured employers 3,329,507.11 *Reprinted, with additions and changes, from New York Evening Post of April 5, 1913, by permission. 15 What the Figures Rereal. These figures are instructive in that they show that the losses, which the fund is called upon to meet, are much larger in the propor- tion of seven to four almost for uninsured than for insured employers. Furthermore, nine-tenths of the losses assumed for the insured were afterward recovered against only 6^ per cent for the uninsured, show- ing that the chances are very slight of recovering any sums paid out for the latter. The net losses in the six years on account of uninsured employers were eighteen times as great as those on account of those in- sured. From the standpoint of affording security for the payment of indemnities to victims of trade accidents, individual insurance by em- ployers in France is therefore not nearly so reliable as that offered by the cooperative societies or stock companies. Next in order may be mentioned Government insurance against ac- cidents as conducted by what is termed the Caisse Nationale d' Assur- ance en Cas d'Accidents. When the law of 1898 was enacted, the authorities feared that, if left without any official competition, the private companies engaged in employer's liability insurance would form a combination among themselves and charge excessive rates. They also believed that the companies might decline certain bad risks, which would compel the employers in such cases to be their own in- surers unless the State furnished them with a haven of refuge. Both of these fears have proved to be absolutely groundless. As insur- ance by the State was intended only to act as a curb on and as a sup- plement to the operations of the private companies, the Caisse onl> Free Adult. Scholastic. societies. Expenses 49,586,850 3,733,487 7,752,170 Surplus income 14,681,324 567,027 3,263,819 Available resources . . 262,848,360 6,548,968 47,731,630 Pension funds 222,400,243 7,819,219 Totals 485,248,603 14,368,186 All the societies combined thus show available resources of 547,- 348,419 francs. Passing now to the number of beneficiaries and the nature of the relief afforded by the various societies in 1908, the following figures are of interest: Approved Societies > Free Adult. Scholastic, societies. Total. Sick 560,884 Pensioners 177,380 Funeral benefits . . 22,692 Widows and orphans 21,301 Aged 7,461 Confirmed invalids 4,420 Total, all societies 83,721 195 96,864 8,811 2,979 2,112 1,106 588 741,469 186,191 25,866 23,4ia 8,56T 5,008 990,514 35 r Approved Societies- Adult. Scholastic. 8,048,454 1,990,860 Daily sick benefit (francs) 1 34 462 Sick benefit per member (francs) . Cost medical attendance (francs) . . Cost medicines (francs) 29.66 11.44 5,190,780. 10,819 5,916,092 8,954 Sick benefits paid in cash (francs) Funeral benefits 10,789,995 921,421 1,558,590 4,040 Widows and orphans 1,815,474 Aged 375,198 Chronic invalids 232,485 Pensions and saving funds (francs) 13,758,455 2,374,230 Free societies. 1,549,404 1.56 31.87 630,775 848,013 2,419,978 196,460 906,026 96,713 45,040 1,348,975 Thus the total monetary relief afforded in one shape or another was not far from thirty-six million francs. The average retiring pension obtained in the approved adult societies varied from 75 to 80 francs. For the free societies, the corresponding figure was 153 francs. The management expenses of the approved adult societies were 2,531,083 francs or 5.1 per cent of all expenditures; of the scholastic 195,629 or 5.23 per cent and of the free societies 333,729 or 4.32 per cent. As to the subventions granted to the societies by the State in one form or another, the same reached the total of 10,287,465 francs in 1908. Of this amount 8,996,705 francs came from the central government; 920,536 from the various communes and 370,224 from the different de- partments. The approved societies alone benefited by these subven- tions, with the exception of 50,604 francs granted by certain depart- ments and communes to the free societies. One notable feature of the mutual sickness insurance societies is their small average membership 134 and 216 active members in 1908 for the free and approved adult societies respectively. In this re- spect they lag behind the sickness societies in Germany and Austria, where the average number of members is 500 and 1,000. But while there is a steady increase in the cost on account of sickness in Germany, where the insurance is compulsory and overseen by the State, the op- posite tendency prevails in the French mutual societies. The following table shows this: Cases of Sickness Per 100 Insured. 1898. 1903. 1908. 1910. Approved adult societies 33.28 29.25 23.08 20.99 Free societies 33.60 27.79 25.22 18.33 German societies 35. 37. 43.2 43.3* Days of Sickness Per Case. Approved adult societies 21.39 22.30 22.57 21.96 Free societies 18.55 21.41 20.49 18.33 German societies 17.6 19. 19.63 19.7* *For 1911. 36 Days of Sickness Per Year Per 100 Insured. Approved adult societies 712 652 521 4(51 Free societies 623 595 517 387 German societies 616 701 848 853* According to the above figures, there are now 90 per cent more days of sickness among every 100 workmen insured in Germany than among the members of the French mutual sickness societies. Among the latter, too, the cases of sickness per 100 insured are one-third less than ten years ago, while among the Germans they are one- third greater. To account for this difference and for the opposite tendencies prevailing in the two countries is difficult. Germany is be- coming more and more an industrial nation, where the conditions of life are more strenuous, while France still remains largely a country of small landowners and shopkeepers. Doubtless, too, the French mutual societies with their smaller membership are able to exercise a better control over their members than is the case with the German sickness societies. It should be further noted that in Germany the average annual con- tribution per member increased in the period 1892-1907 from $4.14 to $6.19 or 50 per cent. In France the contribution from active members is much lower and shows rather a declining tendency. For the adult approved societies, it fell from $2.89 in 1898 to $2.60 and $2.36 in 1903 and 1908, respectively. Benefits per member have remained about the same in France, while in Germany they have shown a marked rise coincident with the increase in the amount of sickness and in the sum total of contributions. Although the mutual sickness societies in France have made such great strides in numbers and adherents since 1898, they are as yet largely confined to the more important centres of population. Instead of a network of societies covering the whole country, the larger part of the rural districts possess none. Thus in 1908 out of the 36,222 com- munes in France, societies were only to be found in 8,548 or 24 per cent. 424 out of 2,911 cantons, or 15 per cent were likewise without any societies. There is therefore a large extent of territory to which the operations of the societies could be extended. Again the societies are weak in the number of women members. In 1908 women comprised but 551,105 out of a total active membership in the free and approved adult societies of 3,462,924, or 15 per cent, as against 35 per cent in the German sickness societies. French mutual societies have thus by no means reached the limit of possible growth. Indeed if sickness insurance among workmen in France were as widespread as in Germany, their active membership should exceed eight millions or almost double the number reported at the end of 1908. That their membership is still increasing rapidly ap- *For 1911. 37 pears from the statement recently published in the daily press that their total number of adherents to-day of all classes is six millions as against 4,694,000 on December 31st, 1908. A contributing cause to this growth is the provision in the new law making insurance against old age disabilities compulsory, by which the State assumes one-sixth of a workman's contribution for such insurance provided he can show that he is insured against sickness in a mutual society and is paying 6 francs a year as premium therefor. OLD AGE PENSION LEGISLATION IN FRANCE. Reasons for Its Non-Success and Unpopularity. No sooner had the French legislature in 1898 passed the law pro- viding for the compulsory insurance of workingmen against accidents than the question of providing old age pensions for laborers began to be agitated. It was generally admitted that something should be done in that direction, but public opinion was divided as to the best method to be followed. The choice lay between a system of compulsory insurance such as enforced in Germany, or the plan of teaching and helping workmen to insure themselves by making use of and encouraging the establishment of voluntary associations like the Mutual Aid Societies. Although the result of a canvas made in 1903 showed that an over- whelming majority of the Chambers of Commerce and of the various labor organizations were opposed to any form of compulsory insurance, the French lawmakers decided to adopt the German system. Even if opposed by public sentiment, they concluded that compulsory insur- ance was the only means by which the careless or improvident workman could be made to help provide for himself a pension against old age disabilities. Voluntary state aided insurance, they believed, would not accomplish sufficient in this direction to make its adoption desirable. Without attempting a minute description, it suffices to say that the French law provides for the compulsory insurance of all salaried employees who earn less than 3,000 francs, or $600, a year. Instead of a sliding scale, based on a division into wage classes as in Germany, all workers, regardless of the wages earned, pay the same fixed amount, namely, nine, six and four and a half francs each year for men, women and children, respectively. The employer has to contribute an amount equal to that paid by his employee. When the retiring age limit of 60 years has been reached (in Germany and England the limit is 70 years), the French Government adds 100 francs or $20 each year to every individual pension. This amount is increased 10 per cent whenever the insured can show that three of his children survived at the age of six- teen years. In normal cases the workman must make 30 annual pay- ments before he becomes entitled to a pension. Each year of military service for the man and every child borne by a woman counts as a year of payment. For employees earning from 3,000 to 5,000 francs a year and for tenants, small farmers and shopkeepers without fixed salaries, volun- tary insurance is permissible, with nine francs annually as the mini- mum and eighteen as the maximum payment. A bonus equal to one- half of the insured's payment is added by the Government each year, but in no case more than sufficient to increase the retiring pension by 100 francs a year. If desired, both compulsory and voluntarily in- sured workmen can let their pensions accumulate until they have reached the age of 65 years, in which event the retiring pension is very much higher than at 60 years in some cases two-thirds. While 39 in Germany the maximum pension at 70 years has been $58 and the average pension but $41, the highest possible pension in France at 65 years is $110. No statistics are yet available as to what is the average pension in France. At the time the French law was enacted, the assertion was made that out of the 22 million adult population, 12 millions would be en- rolled as compulsorily insured and that the adhesion of six million more voluntarily insured workers might be expected. Just as in Germany, where 11^ million workmen were enrolled the first year after a simi- lar statute was passed, the supporters of the French act expected an as equally prompt and universal enlistment on the part of the French laborers. The contrary, however, has proved to be the case. In place of 25 million dollars realized from the contributions of employers and employees during the first year of the operation of the German law, the corresponding receipts during the first twelve months of the French act were only $5,700,000. The French law took effect on July 3rd, 1911, and is therefore now in its second year. The receipts for that year are running higher than for the first and at the rate of fifty million francs, or ten million dollars a year. This means, if 14 francs be taken as the average individual contribution, that only about three and one-half million laborers have been brought under the provisions of the law, or only about one person in ten. Contrast this with the showing in Germany, where one person out of every four is insured against old age disabilities. The government claims an enrollment of almost eight millions, including about 800,000 voluntarily insured work- men; but its figures are thoroughly distrusted and are not borne out by the published table of receipts of contributions. These have been practically stationary for the last six months, and according to the Government's own figures, the number of employees insured has in- creased only two per cent during the last quarter. In other words, the law is not making headway, and the French working classes are persistently refusing to accept its benefits. As an evidence of this may be cited the experience of a group of landowners who offered to pay out of their own pockets the contributions required of their agri- cultural laborers, thus securing to the latter the benefits of the law free of charge. To their astonishment, the laborers one and all de- clined to become insured even on those terms. That the authorities are thoroughly dissatisfied with the results thus far obtained is evi- denced by the Government's proposal to amend the law so as to compel all employers to report what employees are not obeying its provisions and to deduct from every salary the amount of the workman's contri- bution, irrespective of his consent. Why is it that the French working population are so unwilling and reluctant to accept the benefits of this legislation, while in Germany a similar statute has met with universal and prompt acceptance? The answer to this question is to be found in the failure of the French legislators to adopt a system of old age insurance suited to the habits and mental attitude of their people. The idea of old age pensions is 40 not repugnant to the French workman, but the Prussian bureaucratic way of providing for it does not appeal to him. Not the principle, but the method, is what he objects to. Insurance against old age disabilities is nothing more than a system of enforced saving by which the laborer is compelled to set aside or contribute part of his earnings so that he will not be without resources when his strength begins to decline and he can no longer find work. But in France thrift does not have to be taught, it is practised by all classes and from the earliest years. Little school children are enrolled in mutual aid societies to which they contribute two cents a week. There are over 2,300 such societies for public school children, with a membership of 818,000 pupils. When the children leave school their deposits are returned to them and the opening of a savings account through the post office is made possible. The first step towards the securing of a retiring pension has thus been taken. Generally, however, a pension or annuity is not the object saved for, but rather the acquisition in time of a small plot of land or of a little shop. In other words, the French laborer aims to be inde- pendent and to be able to invest his savings as he deems best. This ingrained desire for liberty of action on the part of the race was lost sight of by the French legislators when they decided to follow the German system of old age pensions for workmen. The German people are accustomed to a minute Government supervision of their method of living and of their private affairs and to implicitly obey official regulations. To the Frenchman, however, the complicated formalities and the involved workings of the German plan, where the individual has no control over the disposition of his own savings, are extremely dis- tasteful. Nor do the French seem to possess a sufficiently expert body of officials capable of handling efficiently the elaborate governmental machinery required. The payment of pensions is in many cases six months in arrears, and complaints are universal of the long delays in the carrying out of the provisions of the law. Even if these adminis- trative difficulties be overcome, there is little likelihood of the statute ever becoming very popular. In time, by amendments the present mil- lions of the recalcitrant workers may be brought into line and compelled to comply with the law; but it will be a forced and unwilling adhesion. Possibly, too, as urged by many prominent men, the whole system may be changed, the obligatory features modified and more encouragement given to individual initiative and to private organizations. That would be the more desirable method. The lesson to be derived from French legislation on this subject is plain. In devising a new law to cover any branch of workingmen's insurance, the greatest care should be taken to secure the adoption of a measure that will conform to or fit in with the habits and disposi- tions of the working people. Because a certain system has produced satisfactory results and run smoothly in one country is no reason why it should be blindly followed in another. Only when a law complies with public sentiment will it find a prompt and universal acceptance, without which successful operation cannot be anticipated. 41 HOLLAND. WORKMEN'S ACCIDENT COMPENSATION. How Insured. Functions Performed by the State. Extent of Abuses. Some Defects. Under the Dutch common law, an employer could not be held re- sponsible for an accident to an employee where the same resulted from an act of God, an unknown cause or through the laborer's negligence. That, of course, resulted in an unsatisfactory state of affairs, which was not materially helped by the placing of employers' liability risks with private insurance companies. Those insurers paid only small sums in proportion to the injuries and then often only after contests. Yet, in spite of the example set by Germany almost a decade before, compulsory insurance of workingmen against accidents did not come into force in Holland, until February 1st, 1903. Originally the intention was apparently to follow the Austrian law as a model. The idea of compelling employers to group themselves into associations for accident insurance purposes was, however, aban- doned on the plea that the country was too small and the number of employers in many forms of industrial pursuits too limited to make the establishment of such associations desirable. As just recently in Switzerland, a bitter struggle took place between the advocates and opponents of establishing a State monopoly of this form of insurance. In the lower house, where the labor and socialistic element was most strongly represented, the vote was overwhelmingly in favor of monopoly and against freedom of choice. Owing, however, to the obstinate re- sistance of the upper chamber the monopoly plan was finally defeated and free competition between State and every other form of accident insurance allowed. This outcome has proved very fortunate for the employers, as State insurance has turned out to be the most costly of all. Underlying the Dutch law is the false idea that this form of enact- ment is class legislation, in which the interests of employers and em- ployees are opposed. Thence the theory that the rights of the victim of an accident will not be safeguarded if the employer has any say as to the method of treatment. For this reason the injured workman is given the right of selecting his own physician and a Government of- ficial is made to intervene at every turn between the employer and the workman. The State alone, through its own medical department, de- termines the extent of the disability incurred and the compensation to be paid. Not only does the Government fix, but it also pays out the indem- nity awarded to the victim, in weekly installments. No contact between employer and employee after an accident is, therefore, the rule. This 42 fact should be borne in mind before proceeding to a detailed examina- tion of the workings of the law. Leaving for later discussion the question of how the various sys- tems of insurance are faring in this open but not on an equal footing competition, the first thing to consider is the number of workmen af- fected by and of injuries reported under the law. This is shown in the following table, which covers only serious injuries that lasted over two days and for which an indemnity was paid. No. No. Under Over Year. workmen. accidents. 6 weeks. 6 weeks. Deaths. 1903 . . 455,365 30,020 26,594 3,176 250 1904 . . 508,356 39,136 34,495 4,408 233 1905 . . 528,820 44,219 39,204 4,782 233 1906 . . 557,992 51,337 45,631 5,470 236 1907 .. 574,472 54,458 48,304 5,894 260 1908 .. 586,427 49,799 44,463 5,102 234 1909 .. 605,450 48,377 43,514 4,622 241 1910 .. 631,307 48,782 43,825 4,700 257 1911 .. 650,000 52,741 47,552 4,923 266 1912 669,000 Accidents per Under Over Year. 1,000 workmen. 6 weeks. 6 weeks. Deaths. 1903 .. 65.9 58.4 5.4 0.54 1904 .. 77. 67.9 6.8 0.46 1905 .. 83.6 74.1 6.8 0.45 1906 .. 92. 81.7 7.4 0.44 1907 .. 94.8 84. 8.2 0.48 1908 .. 84.9 75.8 6.8 0.42 1909 .. 79.9 71.9 5.8 0.41 1910 .. 77.5 69.6 5.6 0.42 1911 81.2 74. 7.6 0.41 The following figures have been published as yet only for the period 1903-1910: Permanent Per Average r-- -Disability N Year. disability 1,000 disability 25% 25- 50- 75- cases, workmen, per cent, or less. 50%. 75%. 100%. 1903 . . 657 1.54 45.01 33.2 33.9 16.7 16.2 1904 .. 890 1.89 43.46 35.7 30.5 18.3 15.5 1905 .. 1,152 2.24 39.09 41.3 33. 13.3 12.4 1906 .. 1,261 2.43 36.88 44.2 32.3 14.4 9.1 1907 .. 1,224 2.14 35.98 46.3 31.1 14.9 7.7 1908 .. 1,109 1.93 34.52 51.2 29.1 12.3 7.4 1909 .. 1,125 1.90 34.38 50.6 30.9 12.1 6.4 1910 . . 1,071 1.84 32.19 57.5 26. 10.0 6.5 In 1910, the average premium charged by the state insurance de- partment or bank was 2.73%. In relation to wages, losses in Holland and Austria since 1903 have run as follows: Year. 1903. 1904. 1905. 1906. Austria , .. 1.91 . .. 1.95 ... 1.95 . 2.09 Holland. 1.54 1.82 1.91 2.00 Year. 1907, 1908, 1909 1910 Austria. . . 1.95 , .. 1.86 . .. 1.57 . 1.40 Holland. 1.92 1.63 1.54 1.40 The following is the rate of accidents per 1,000 workmen in the dif- ferent trade groups for the same years: Group. I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IX. X. XL XII. XIII. XIV. XV. XVI. XVII. XVIII. 1903. Pottery, glass, lime, etc 64.9 Precious stones 17.5 Printing and lithographing . . . 19.4 Building and engineering 89.4 Chemicals and explosives .... ,40.1 Wood, cork and straw 61.8 Clothing and cleaning 20.3 Fine arts 23.6 Leather, rubber, etc 30.3 Minerals, coal, etc 61.4 Metals 78.1 Machinery, etc 116.3 Ships and vehicles 117.3 Paper products, etc 44.4 Textiles 21. Gas and electricity 57.8 Food products 47.7 Trade and transportation ... 71.9 1905. 1907. 1909. 1910. 90.2 113. 96.38 98.88 13. 17.6 14.48 15.04 28.4 31.5 30.97 28.25 112.2 119.3 102.60 99.38 52.5 62. 51.44 57.98 85.9 100.1 90.30 88.63 21. 25.8 24.33 23.74 56.8 49.2 30. 23.20 48.3 55. 50.81 49.12 96.3 118.8 147.49 170.82 115.6 129.6 112.21 107.72 134.1 152.9 132.89 126.67 153.7 198.3 165.08 138.46 51.4 64.8 61.68 56.50 26.7 34.9 27.07 27.44 65.7 75.1 53.37 54.40 62.4 70.6 63.18 61.75 87.9 95. 71.90 69.43 65.9 83.5 94.8 79.94 77.52 As in almost all other countries the percentage of cases involving death or permanent disability remains about the same. Whatever in- crease has occurred has taken place in the minor accidents entailing a disability of less than six weeks' duration. It is to be noted that up to 1907, accidents increased both in total and in relative number. Since that date, however, there has been quite a decline in both respects, due largely to a stricter control exercised by the Government officials. In this regard, Holland is having a hap- pier experience than France, where accidents show an almost uninter- rupted gain from year to year. This difference is all the more striking because some false rules are followed in the interpretation and adminis- tration of the Dutch law, which afford opportunities for abusive prac- tices. In the first place, the Government physicians who, in every in- 44 stance, determine the extent of the injuries received by the victim of an accident, base their appraisal on the theoretical impairment suffered and not on the actual loss in wages incurred. For example, if a laborer loses an eye, he is deemed to be 30 per cent less efficient than before and receives an annuity accordingly. Yet his work may have been of a comparatively simple nature, which he is able to perform just as well after as before his accident. If given his full wages again, besides the indemnity awarded him, he will receive much higher pay than an able- bodied workman with unimpaired vision. In order to avoid having workmen, who have been formerly injured, receive more than the pre- vailing rate of wages, the large employers exchange lists containing the names of such employees as are known to be in receipt of weekly indemnities. If one applies for work he will not be taken on unless he will agree to a reduction in the amount of the usual weekly wage by the sum received by him as an indemnity. Consequently, whenever he can, the workman tries to conceal from his employer the fact that he is drawing a regular pension on account of an injury previously incurred. If he succeeds, his salary is higher than that of the ordinary laborer doing the same work, while if he fails the employer reaps the benefit of the indemnity through not having to pay the full rate of wages. In either case, someone makes a profit out of the pension, which, of course, is wrong. Atonement for an actual wage loss suffered is the only cor- rect rule to be followed in settling for workingmen's accidents. Any other method is a direct incentive to the laborer to exaggerate the ex- tent of his injuries as much as possible. Indeed, while much better kept in check than in some other coun- tries, exaggeration and simulation of accidents by workmen are not unknown and are much complained of by employers, especially the former evil. In general, the same drawbacks to the compulsory work- men's accident insurance are to be observed in Holland as elsewhere. A hurt that would not ordinarily cause a stoppage of work in a com- pulsorily insured trade results in a cessation of labor, and an injury to an insured employee takes much longer to heal than if he were unin- sured. Another incentive to prolonged and unnecessary idleness on the part of those injured exists in Holland through workmen obtaining benefits from outside sources in addition to the amount alloted to them by the accident insurance law. The amount is fixed at 70 per cent of their usual wage. If, in addition, they receive monetary assistance from a fraternal order, their total income frequently becomes greater during the period of disability than while they were at work. In one instance, half of the workmen treated were receiving from 90 to 150 per cent of their usual salaries. Under such circumstances laborers will naturally delay resuming work as long as they can. The experience of the Dutch nation in this respect emphasizes the necessity of not putting the scale of compensation for accidents at too high a figure. The injured laborer should always be under a strong pecuniary in- centive to resume his employment. The possibility also of obtaining 45 benefits in excess of the usual wage through carrying outside insur- ance should be strictly guarded against and forbidden, as in the re- cently adopted Swiss law. Although injured workmen have the right of selecting the physicians who shall treat them, the grave abuses that have resulted elsewhere from the adoption of this system are hardly to be found in Holland. Medical costs per accident and in the aggregate have remained about the same. Various reasons account for this difference from the experi- ence of France, where free choice by the laborer of his medical iat- tendant also prevails, with a resultant constantly augmenting burden of expenditure. In the first place, the physician's role in Holland is limited to treating the injured party. He has nothing to say as to the compensation to be paid the victim, which is fixed by a Government official. There is thus no opportunity for the exploitation of the em- ployer through doctors and workmen acting in collusion and making false statements as to injuries. Secondly, Holland is a small country, with only 2,500 physicians in active practice. It is easy therefore for the authorities to keep tab on each individual practitioner and to call him sharply to account if his treatment of accident cases is unnecessarily prolonged and the convalescence of his patients unusually slow. Besides, a doctor caught in improper practices may have his license to treat accident cases revoked. A third and important deterrent is found in the clause of the Dutch accident law, which permits the employer to prescribe the first aid treatment to an injured employee. How important the provision is will appear from the following table: Total No. injuries Total No. injuries accidents cured within accidents cured with- Year. reported. 2 days. Year. reported, in 2 days. 1903 38,706 8,686 1908 65,550 15,571 1904 49,667 10,531 1909 64,404 16,027 1905 55,497 11,272 1910 66,086 17,304 1906 64,864 13,527 1911 71,731 18,990 1907 68,994 14,536 As the law prescribes that no indemnity shall be paid unless the dis- ability resulting from an injury exceeds two days, the figures in the second column give the number of accidents reported which either re- sulted in no harm being done or which were cured in two days' time through the use of simple medical surface applications. These form one-quarter of all, and about the treatment of them the employer has the say and the workman has practically no voice in the selection of the physician. This is a very valuable privilege for the employers and checks dishonest practices, as the following illustration will show: In some of the larger industrial plants, surgical rooms are established with a company doctor frequent in attendance. No matter how trifling his hurt may be, a workman is obliged, under penalty of instant dis- missal, to report at once as soon as he suffers an injury at the doctor's headquarters for treatment. Suppose something has flown into his 46 eye. The offending particle is forthwith removed, and the physician can tell at once whether the patient should continue work or not. If the injury is found to be a slight one, the laborer knows that it will be useless for him to attempt to magnify it into an excuse for not working, even though he can find an easy-going physician willing to substantiate his claim. Not only does the prompt first aid treatment furnished by the employer thus prevent any exaggeration or simulation of injuries, but it also greatly lessens the chances of a wound leading to a prolonged disability through neglect or lack of treatment in its early stages. On the question of medical treatment, therefore, the experience of Holland cannot be cited as an argument in favor of the free choice of the physician by the workingmen. If abuses have been kept down, it has been due to limiting the choice in part and to other favoring cir- cumstances, like the strict control possible in a small country. Black sheep exist among the members of the medical profession in all the large centres, who would be only too ready to mulct the employers if the opportunity arose through aiding injured laborers to make un- founded and exaggerated claims. Dissatisfaction on the part of the workingmen with the amounts awarded them, so prevalent in Germany, hardly exists in Holland. Appeals to the courts especially established to pass on disputed ques- tions arising out of the accident insurance law are comparatively in- frequent. In 1911, 1,650 cases were decided in the first appeal court of which only 1,284 related to questions of indemnity. Mention may be made here that the Dutch law does not permit the settlement of small annuities by the payment of a lump sum, as allowed in France. But in Holland, instead of the employer, it is the Government office which has the burden of making these small regular payments, on each re- curring Tuesday, amounting in some cases to only a few cents a week. That requires much additional bookkeeping and is one cause why the administrative expenses of the State insurance department are so high. As a whole, it may be said that, while the law has some serious de- fects, workingmen's accident insurance in Holland has not produced the baneful effects to be found elsewhere. In spite of the increased strain on laborers due to the greater industrial activity and attendant over- time working during the last few years, accidents are relatively less in number than in 1904. Fraudulent and simulated accidents are guarded against. Collusive practices between physicians and workmen are almost impossible on account of the strict control and settlement of claims by Government officials, whose probity and uprightness are very high. Yet one must admit that owing to certain defects inherent in every system of government administration, the role played by the State in Holland has very considerably increased the burden on industry from workingmen's accidents. What those defects are and how they tend to unduly raise costs can be most clearly brought out by passing to an examination of State as contrasted with private insurance in the matter of employers' liability risks. 47 DUTCH EXPERIENCE IN STATE VERSUS PRIVATE INSURANCE. Higher Cost and Disadvantages of Former. Disappearance of Self In- surance, Eclipse of Corporate Insurance and Rise of Mutual Insurance. In Holland, as in France, all forms of insurance are available to the employer. He may carry the risk himself, become a member of a cooperative or mutual insurance association, insure himself in a stock company or place his insurance in the State insurance department, which bears the title of Royal Insurance Bank. While these various systems are open to all alike, they are far from competing on equal terms. Employer's self insurance is under the greatest handicap of all and is, consequently, the least favored. On the other hand, the Royal or State Bank enjoys certain important advantages, which ought to put it in the lead of all rivals. To begin with, the debit-side of accident insurance underwriting is made up practically of two items administrative expenses and losses. Now, because under the Dutch system, accident claims are settled for all writers of risks through the State Bank, rival insurers are unable to secure any advantage over that institution in the important matter of losses. No opportunity is afforded them to demonstrate that they can adjust losses more expeditiously or more cheaply than the Government officials. Only in the item of expenses have they a chance to better the record of the State Bank. Here, however, the contest is again un- equal. Every risk not placed elsewhere falls to the Government insti- tution, which thereby is dispensed from the necessity of employing an agency force. Furthermore, it enjoys the use of the mails free of charge. Again, half of all the salaries of the higher officials of the bank, or about two-fifths of its total administrative expenses, are paid by the central Government. The remaining three-fifths are divided among all those insuring workingmen's risks according to the amounts respectively underwritten by them. Thus, if in any given year the private insurers insure one-half of all workers salaries, such insurers would then be called upon to pay one-half of 60 per cent, or 30 per cent, of the State Bank's administrative expenses. In other words, be- sides meeting their own quota of expenses they must also contribute largely towards those of an institution carrying on an insurance busi- ness in competition with themselves. With various expense items, which its competitors are called upon to meet, thus taken care of, the State Bank, whose aim is to furnish in- surance at cost and not for a profit, ought to be in a position to make lower premium rates than anyone else. One would expect therefore to find by far the larger part of existing accident risks insured with the 48 State institution. Such has, however, not proved to be the case, as a glance at the following table will show: Total salaries Year. Florins. 1903 226,046,000 1904 251,212,700 1905 264,803,000 1906 280,799,800 1907 292,401,500 1908 297,164,000 1909 312,092,300 1910 330,612,100 1911 349,761,000 1912 364,000,000 Insured by Year. Mutual Comp. 1903 38,100,000 1904 48,200,000 1905 62,200,000 1906 75,700,000 1907 85,600,000 1908 92,000,000 1909 104,400,000 1910 120,000,000 1911 134,000,000 1912 155,600,000 Salaries open to Insured by competition. State Bank. Pet. 198,565,000 72,341,000 36.4 219,460,000 65,891,000 30. 230,780,000 66,356,000 28.8 240,890,000 69,925,000 28.6 254,607,000 89,879,000 35.2 256,224,000 124,323,000 48.5 271,000,000 132,800,000 48.6 285,700,000 136,500,000 48. 300,950,000 134,525,000 44.7 134,000,000 Pet. 19.2 22. 26.9 30.9 33.5 35.9 38.5 42. 47.8 Insured by Stock Comp. 88,124,000 105,358,000 102,224,000 99,300,000 79,100,000 39,891,000 33,800,000 29,200,000 32,400,000 Pet. 43.4 48 43.3 40.5 31.3 15.6 12.9 10. 7.5 In the column of total salaries insured are included the wages paid by those employers carrying their own insurance. These are now but a handful in number, comprising the leading municipalities, certain Government departments and the principal railway system, which have always insured their own risks. The wages paid by these self insurers should therefore be deducted, as has been done in the second column, in order to obtain a correct estimate of the total percentage of business open to competition secured by the several systems of insurance. While permissible on making a minimum deposit of 30,000 florins, self insur- ance by individual industrial employers no longer occurs. One reason for this is that, if an accident happens, the full purchase value of the in- jured man's annuity must be deposited by the insurer with the Gov- ernment bank, either in cash or in the shape of securities. If he is the employer himself, no part of this fund is ever returned, even though the victim should die the next day. A corporation, on the other hand, would in such case receive its securities back. On account of this dis- crimination and because those insured in a large organization obtain certain advantages free of cost, such as advice in legal matters, em- ployers' self-insurance by owners of industrial plants has been elimi- 49 nated in Holland, leaving only State, mutual and corporate insurance to dispute the field. This last branch is only open to domestic corpora- tions all foreign companies being excluded. Besides the State Bank, there were originally in competition eight stock companies and one employers' mutual association. At the begin- ning, the stock companies were far ahead in the amount of business se- cured and held their own until 1907. In that year, one of the com- panies, owing to heavy losses sustained, ceased insuring risks and was followed later by three other companies, leaving only four active to-day. The salaries insured by these companies declined rapidly after 1906, until 1909, since which date the amount has remained almost stationary. It is evident therefore that the stock companies, handicapped as they are, have been conducting a losing fight. Nevertheless, they are able to hold their own and underbid the State Bank on one-tenth of the possi- ble business. That they find it profitable to accept these risks at lower terms than demanded by the Government clearly shows the premium rates of the State Bank to be in many instances too high. As the authorities move slowly in changing rates, the stock companies will probably hereafter always find some lines of accident insurance which they can handle to advantage. Employers, who would rather pay a fixed premium, will always prefer them to a mutual organization, where the rate varies according to losses incurred. But, so long as conditions in Holland remain unchanged, they will continue to play only a minor role in the insurance of accident compensation. Like that of the stock companies, the amount of salaries insured by the State Bank remained stationary until 1906. With the decline of the companies in 1907, the figures of the bank begin to rise. In 1910 they reached their maximum and have since remained at the same figure, with a decline in the relative percentage of all open risks under- written from 48 to 43 per cent. State insurance in Holland appears therefore to have passed its zenith and to be now on the decline. After having held the lead for the four years 1907-1911 in the amount of salaries insured, the State Bank in 1912 dropped to second place, having been out-distanced by its strongest and most successful competitor, the Employers' Mutual Association. Although the total of workers' salaries insured increased some 10 per cent between 1910 and 1912, the amount insured in the State Bank barely held its own. Whatever new business offers itself now is secured by its competitors. From the outset, it was easy to foresee that employers mutual or cooperative insurance would be the kind most likely to make headway against the system of Government insurance in vogue in Holland. Furnishing its members protection against risks at cost price, dis- pensing with an agency force and all participants directly profiting through losses being kept down, this form of private insurance should compete on more equal terms than any other with the State Bank. Such, indeed, has proved to be the case as the figures of its steady and uninterrupted growth from year to year in the amount of salaries underwritten plainly indicates. Starting in 1903 with the least amount 50 of all or only one-fifth of all salaried risks, mutual insurance took the lead in 1912 with 47 per cent of all risks covered. In nine years, its business has quadrupled, while that of the State Bank has merely doubled. In Holland, therefore, employers' mutual has to-day outstripped and surpassed State insurance in amount, through being able to offer lower rates than those demanded by the Government authorities. Its striking superiority in this respect is clearly demonstrated by the following table: Salaries insured Prem. based Actual in mut. system, on gov. rates. prem. paid. Year. Florins. Florins. Florins. 1903 38,100,000 865,000 729,000 1904 48,200,000 1,121,000 1,060,000 1905 62,200,000 1,537,000 1,335,000 1906 75,500,000 1,776,000 1,490,000 1907 85,600,000 2,021,000 1,599,000 1908 92,000,000 2,449,000 1,575,000 1909 104,400,000 3,310,000 2,133,000 1910 120,000,000 4,187,000 2,346,000 1911 136,000,000 4,703,000 2,808,000 1912 155,600,000 5,310,000 3,327,000 Total 917,800,000 4 7,279,000 18,402,000 Saving over Year. gov. figures. Pet. 1903 136,000 15.7 1904 61,000 5.4 1905 202,000 13.1 1906 286,000 16.1 1907 422,000 20.9 1908 874,000 35.7 1909 1,177,000 35.6 1910 1,841,000 44. 1911 1,895,000 40.3 1912 1,983,000 37.4 Total 8,877,000 32.5 To the above figure of savings should be added the sum of 139,000 florins found to have been overcharged the mutual association for losses from 1903-1907. The total actual saving is thus brought up to 9,016,000 florins or 33 per cent over what the employers would have had to pay if they had been obliged to insure with the State. If the State pre- miums be estimated at 100, mutually insured employers paid one-third less or at the rate of 67. In other words, the average premiums de- manded by the Government for the ten years 1903-1912 have been al- 51 most 50 per cent higher than what those insured mutually have found sufficient to meet all losses and expenses. And even with its two-fifths higher premiums and with the major part of its administrative expenses contributed from outside sources, the State Bank failed to come out even. At the end of 1911, the total deficit in its accounts figured about 1,800,000 florins. The excessive cost in Holland of the Government sys- tem of insurance as compared with that offered by a well-managed and economically run private organization is thus conclusively proven. The question may be asked, why, if so much more costly, the State Bank should yet be able to secure two-fifths of all the possible busi- ness. The answer is to be found in the fact that Holland is a country where small employers predominate and where large industrial estab- lishments are comparatively few in number. The last available statistics show that in 1910 there were 89,728 employers insured, with 631,307 workmen, or seven workmen on the average for each separate employer. For the State Bank alone the figures were 75,179 employers and 291,731 workmen, or 4 workmen per employer, showing that the less im- portant risks were generally insured with the Government office. This has been the case from the start. The small employer with only two or three workmen to insure is under no particular inducement to make a change because the total premium he has to pay is not large in amount and the possible saving to be effected would not in any case exceed a few dollars. Consequently, he is apt to stick to the State Bank, while establishments of any size or importance, as a rule, insure elsewhere. But for this hold upon the small employers, the amount of insurance effected through the Government office would be very much less. In order to ascertain why Government insurance is so much more expensive, one need only contrast the methods of the State Bank with those of the Employers' Mutual Association. This latter, known as the Central Bank for Employers' Risks, is an incorporated association, on January 1, 1913, serving the interests of 5,275 employers, with some 267,000 workmen in their pay. Its members consist of 96 large em- ployers carrying their risks directly with the Central Bank, and 41 af- filiated mutual associations, to which the remaining 5,179 employers belong, with an average membership of 130 employers each. Each as- sociation levies its own premiums based on losses suffered and on its quota of the expenses of the Central Bank. That Bank, in turn, acts as a clearing house for all the associations, settles all losses as called upon by the State Bank, provides a legal bureau to pass on disputed claims and maintains a technical department for the inspection of plants and to suggest safeguards against accidents. Through adopting the plan of dividing its members into small groups and making each group responsible for accident losses suffered in the establishments of those belonging to it, every individual em- ployer insured in the Central Bank is under the strongest possible stimulus to reduce the number of accidents as much as possible among his employees. If the indemnities paid his workmen for injuries re- ceived in any given year are materially cut down, the owner knows 52 that it means a saving to him in the shape of a reduced premium. He has the greatest incentive therefore to adopt safety appliances and to enforce the observance of preventive rules. Contrast to this attitude, the position of an employer insured in the State Bank. Once he has paid his premium, it is immaterial from a pecuniary standpoint whether accidents among his employees occur frequently or not. So long as his equipment measures up to the ordinary standard, he has to fear no in- crease in his premium rates. As one of sixty or more thousand employ- ers insured, any precautions against accidents taken by him in his single establishment will have only a very remote influence, if any, towards lowering the charge for the insurance in his particular industry. Un- able to directly influence results through any especial action of his own, therefore, the employer insured in the State Bank has no particular cause to seek to reduce the number or frequency of accidents. How this indifference as to the number of accidents operates to the disadvantage of the State Bank appears from the following table: Year. Accidents per Million Florin Wages. State. Companies. 1903 153 165 1904 186 186 1905 225 192 1906 262 209 1907 286 207 1908 258 179 1909 236 170 1910 223 171 Accidents, therefore, are considerably more frequent among those insured in the State Bank. Yet the contrary ought to be the case. As has just been pointed out, Holland is a country where small industry prevails. In 1910 69,074 employers, or 78% of all, had 5 workmen or less in their establishments, or a total of 92,802 workmen. Such small employers are the best risks. The official figures of accidents per 1,000 workmen, given below, indicate this: 1903. 1904. 1905. 1906. 1907. 1908. 1909. 1910. For all employers 65.9 77 83.6 92 94.7 68.4 72.9 69.5 For employers with less than 5 workmen 47.7 57.4 64 69.4 73.9 84.9 79.9 77.5 In the latter category, the average number for the eight years comes to 65^, as against 82 in the former. But, as previously indicated, it is just the small and best class of employers from a risk standpoint, which is usually insured in the State Bank. Yet, instead of making a better showing, however, as would be expected, its accident ratio per 1,000 workmen is decidedly higher than that of other insurers. Besides excelling in the number, the State Bank also formerly led in 53 the loss per accident. For the five years 1903-1907, the losses ran in florins as follows: Year. State. Companies. Year. State. Companies. 1903 102.78 90.66 1906 115.67 80.93 1904 112.58 94.24 1907 102.56 74.70 1905 114.34 89.24 An injured workman insured in the State Bank, therefore, received twenty-five per cent more indemnity on the average than one insured elsewhere. That was not due to any favoritism, but rather to lack of proper control by the Government officials. For example, a casual dock laborer injured with one may be able to resume work with an- other employer long before his period of estimated disability has ex- pired. In such a case, the Government officials, having had no adequate system of check, would continue to pay the regular indemnity as before. Those privately insured, however, make it a point to keep tab on their workmen, and the laborer's recovery would in all likelihood be observed and the authorities notified to stop any further payment of indemnity. With a higher average loss and a relatively larger number of acci- dents, it is not surprising to find that in 1907 the total losses of the State Bank amounted to 2.79% of salaries insured, against 1.70% for those of the private companies, or an excess of 64%. Since 1908, however, the showing of the State Bank as regards losses per accident has been as favorable as those of the companies. The last figures reported run as follows: r-Losses per Accident-^ r-Losses to Wages Insured A Year. State. Companies. State. Companies. r- florins -^ r- per cent > 1908 84.57 70.64 2.13 1.41 1909 75.60 80.54 1.74 1.55 1910 69.03 77.79 1.51 1.51 Through having to consider only a comparatively small number, when it comes to an apportionment of losses, the premiums of th,e Central Bank can be more quickly and fairly adjusted to meet actual costs than those of the State institution. The latter has always pro- ceeded on the theory that stability in premium rates is the great thing to be desired. The law itself prescribes that rates shall be revised at the end of every five years, and it is very seldom that any particular rate is altered during the five year period. The red tape that has to be gone through with in each instance acts as a deterrent against effecting any change. Furthermore, in raising or lowering the tariff of charges, the authorities are governed more or less by their official statistics of ac- cidents and losses in the various branches of industry. While very full and complete, their publication must necessarily be several years delayed in each instance on account of their very elaborateness. In- 54 deed, those from 1908 on have yet to be published. Now, in Holland, as elsewhere, accident risks in different branches of trade or industry may change very quickly in this age of invention and improvement, and often from the most unexpected causes. For example, who could have foreseen that employees in butcher shops were to become a much more dangerous accident risk in consequence of meat being delivered in the Dutch cities by young men or boys on bicycles, where formerly they went on foot? Under its methods, a number of years must alwayjs elapse before the State Bank will realize that its premiums in that par- ticular trade are too low to cover the losses, and perhaps an even longer period before its rate will be raised. Unlike the Central Bank, where premiums are automatically adjusted every year to suit the vary- ing results in each particular branch of industry, the rates of the State Bank are generally based on conditions as they were three or four years previous. Consequently, through its inability to speedily change rates, one would naturally expect to find the premiums of the govern- ment institution deviating from the normal more or less and being either too low or too high. And that has proved to be the case. For the first five year period after the enactment of the law, namely, from 1903-1907, the State Bank showed a deficit of 4,189,000 florins, as against total premium receipts of 7,233,000 florins. Of this total deficit, due to a variety of causes, 2,520,000 florins was ascribed to insufficiency of premium receipts. For the Bank to have covered costs, therefore, its premium income should have been over one-third higher. If 100 be taken as the correct standard, the actual premium receipts for 1903-07 were only on the basis of 73. From this era of too low premiums and recurring deficits, we find in the second five year period from 1908-1912 that the Bank has achieved a surplus in every twelve months, or a total profit of about 2,850,000 florins. Its net deficit now stands at about 1,350,000 florins. Taking the figures for 1911, which are the last published, the gross premiums yielded 3,300,000 florins and the profit coming to the bank through excess of premium receipts amounted to 570,000 florins. In- stead of an actual premium rate of 2.44, one of 2.02 per cent would have sufficed for the Bank to have come out even. Its present rates, there- fore, show an excess of over 20% above actual cost figures. For 1910, the excess was 40%. Again, taking the full figures for 1903-1910, the Bank's losses as contrasted with premiums run as follows: Year. Per cent. Year. Per cent. 1903 82.2 1907 154.9 1904 112.4 1908 104.2 1905 149.7 1909 125. 1906 184.9 1910 166.6 Starting with a surplus in 1903, the Bank met with a loss in the next twelve months. If this had occurred to a private company, it is safe to say that rates would have been promptly raised to overcome 55 the deficit. Nothing was done by the officials of the Bank, however, so that its loss in the two following years reached alarming propor- tions. Only in 1907, or three years after the deficit had first de- clared itself, were rates partly raised and the loss partially reduced. The slowness of Government action, even in cases calling for prompt and decisive proceedings, could not be better illustrated. Perhaps the most instructive example of the methods followed by the State Bank is to be found in the insurance of longshoremen, }or those engaged in the loading of ships. As a basis for its tariff the Bank followed the Austrian statistics of 1895 and 1896, showing 48 serious accidents in this calling, involving the payment of 14,732 florins indemnity. On this showing a premium of 2.64 per cent works out. The Bank consequently started with average rates of 4 per cent in this branch. The loading of ships, however, is in Holland a very dangerous occupation, varying in risk according to the size and equipment of the vessel, the manner of loading, whether elevators are used or not, and the intensity or speed with which the work is carried on. From the very start the Bank's premium rate proved to be entirely too low, entailing losses as follows: Losses to Year. Premiums. Losses. Deficit, premiums. 1903 104,078 227,918 123,840 219 1904 112,573 446,632 334,059 396.8 1905 167,044 653,072 486,028 391 1906 . . . . 194,102 867,557 673,455 447 1907 440,264 1,180,101 739,837 268 Although total premiums in 1903, the very first year, did not cover half the losses, the same disastrous rate figure was adhered to for the three following years. Losses increased by leaps and bounds until in 1906 they were four and one-half times the premiums. Finally, in 1907, while the deficit was larger than ever, premium receipts began to rise due to rates having been at last increased. Instead of at 4, as originally, the average rate in this industry at present varies from 15 to 30 per cent. Although the government rates up to 1907 were often too low, they were in frequent instances fixed too high. The following table, giv- ing conditions at the end of 1907, shows this: Per cent of wages insured State Bank Loss outside State Bank. Risks. Premium. Rate. 1903. 1907. Painters 3.673 1.46 81.22 87.30 Plasterers 3.673 2.91 82.15 86.46 Carpenters 4.521 1.92 72.71 81.49 Masons 3.673 2.89 74.38 79.13 In thus quoting and adhering to premiums far in excess of the true risk rate, the Bank made it easy for its rivals to secure from 56 year to year a constantly increasing percentage of the business in the above trades. Looking at the reverse of this picture, the next table illustrates what occurred when the Bank's official rates proved too low to cover losses. Percentage wages insured Risk. outside State Bank. 1903. 1907. Blacksmiths 60.49 26.88 Pottery workers 41.87 0.11 Glass blowers 67.42 0.00 Here other insurers have either wholly or in greater part withdrawn from the field, leaving to the State Bank the doubtful satisfaction of carrying on a losing business more or less alone. Coming back to the variance in methods between the employers mutual or Central Bank and those of the government institution, the branch or minor associations of the former have not only a limited number of members, but are made to include as far as possible only those engaged in one form of industry, for instance, sugar refining or carpet making. This grouping of employers by trades is deemed most desirable both for purposes of general information and because it leads to a better understanding of the causes of and possible preventive measures against accidents in each particular industry. Those en- gaged in the same business can learn far more accurately than can any outsider whether an employer is financially responsible or not, the con- dition his machinery is in, whether or not he has taken proper pre- cautions against accidents in his work-rooms, the state of discipline among his workmen and whether they observe properly precautionary rules and regulations. In this way, the Central Bank obtains a much more accurate knowledge than can its State rival of the degree of risk incurred in different establishments. Each local association has its committee on admissions to pass on the qualifications of candidates; and, as far as practicable, only employers animated with the common purpose of reducing accident losses to the lowest feasible limit and of safeguarding the lives of their employes in every possible respect are taken in. If members fail at any time to install acceptable methods of protection or allow their workmen to become careless in observing rules of safety, they are asked to withdraw. Thus the Central Bank is enabled to carefully guard against losses arising through changes in the degree of risk and to hold its insured employers, through fear of ex- pulsion, up to a high standard in methods of safety. Neither of these conditions exist in the case of the State Bank. It cannot threaten expulsion in case of imperfect equipment, for it must insure all risks. Through its failure to keep in close touch with the changes occurring in classes of or individual risks, it is at a great disadvantage as compared with other insurers. As an instance of this may be cited the case of the blacksmiths. In 1903 they were a 57 fair risk and were insured as such both in the State and Central Banks. By 1906, however, accidents had so increased in this trade that the risk had become a much greater one. Accordingly, we find the Central Bank abandoning this branch of insurance and directing its customers to the State Bank. Later on, when the government rates were raised to correspond with the increase in risk, we find the Cen- tral Bank once more competing for this insurance. Again in 1909, the government premium for peat gatherers was lowered. This was deemed insufficent by the Central Bank to cover losses in that branch. It therefore instantly disbanded its own local association for this trade and had the members insure in the State Bank. In this way, all un- profitable individual or trade risks are unloaded upon the latter in- stitution to the detriment of its finances and to the benefit of those of its competitors. Although its losses from accidents are so very much higher in comparison with those incurred by other insurers, the government in- surance department has made no systematic effort to find out ways of cutting down the number of accidents. Mention has been made before of the Central Bank maintaining a special bureau for this very purpose, which is constantly making valuable suggestions and devising appli- ances for reducing the chances of accidents. The low costs shown by the Central Bank are in no small degree due to the work of this preventive bureau. Frequently it has happened that, where some rec- ommended improvement has entirely done away with a certain kind of accident, the government factory inspectors have then made its adop- tion compulsory. But the point to emphasize is that the invention of such safety devices and improvements is due to private initiative and not to government action. The State follows, but towards the dis- covery of preventive measures it does practically nothing. Compared to losses incurred for workingmen's accidents (which in- clude the indemnities paid for other insurers), the administrative ex- penses of the State Bank run as follows: 1903. 1904. 1905. 1906. 1907. 1908. 1909. 1910. 12.4% 14.5% 19.2% 19.5% 21.5% 25.7% 27.7% 26.5% Unfortunately, only the total of these expenses is given, and no attempt is made to subdivide them. In the nature of things, however, they must run pretty high on account of the centralized system of the bank. Every loss no matter how trivial has to be referred to the head office in Amsterdam for settlement, which entails far more cor- respondence and clerical work than if adjustments were made directly on the spot. The administrative costs show an upward tendency and in 1910 were 21^% of losses and expenses combined. If, in order to put the Bank on an equal footing with a private company, there be added to the percentage of 21.5% for 1910, 10% for the cost of an agency force and 1%% more for free postage, the total expense would be 33 per cent. 58 Advocates of Scate insurance may claim that the superior showing of the Central Bank is due to its system of selected risks. It accepts only those which measure up to a high standard, and rejects all others. If obliged to insure every employer, good, bad or indifferent, as is the State Bank, its saving in expenses over the figures of the government office would not be nearly so great. A comparison between the two systems, it may therefore be contended, is unfair, because they do not serve the same class of risks. In answer to that contention one should recall that both systems are intended to furnish insurance at cost. The odds should be in favor of the State Bank, on account of its having to pay only a part of its own administrative expenses. In 1911 such ex- penses amounted to 1,292,000 florins, of which the State Bank had to meet only 347,000; whereas the Central Bank, besides footing its own administration expenses of 168,500 florins, had to contribute 317,000 florins towards those of the State Bank. If, in spite of this and other advantages, the State Bank, in order to come out even, cannot charge at the rate of 70, like the Central Bank, but is obliged to charge at the rate of 100, either one of two things is clear, namely, either its expenses are unduly higher than those of its rival or its method of determining premium rates is entirely wrong. Assuming that the State were able to operate as cheaply as the Central Bank, it should, if the principle of cost prevails, quote a like figure of 70 for the risks insured with its business opponent. If it pleads inability to do so because obliged to accept the more dangerous and unprofitable risks, which the Central Bank is at liberty to discard, the reply is that the remedy lies in its own hands. Although obliged to insure everyone who applies, the State Bank may fix its own premium rates. It is not obliged to do business at a loss, and, if its tariffs were properly rated and kept up to date, the private companies could not load it down with the unprofitable risks. That they do so is its own fault, and is a grave reflection on its management. Not its obligation to insure all comers, but lax methods and improper adjustment of pre- miums are the cause of its excessive loss ratio. If the experience of the Dutch nation is to count for anything, State insurance of occupa- tional accidents would not appear desirable from any point of view. It is very costly; and, far from being a check upon, it tends to breed indifference as to the number of accidents. In conclusion, the result of the contest in Holland, lasting now for over ten years, between State and private agencies in the field of accident insurance has been to prove the decided superiority of the lat- ter. Official routine methods, slowness of action, tenacious clinging to false ideas and erroneous conceptions mark the proceedings of the one system, against which are to be contrasted up to date measures, prompt adaptation to changing conditions and a constant watch for possible improvements. The outcome strikingly confirms the opinion of those who believe that individual effort and private initiative can always be counted upon to produce better results than can be secured by entrusting the conduct of an ordinary business to the State. 59 AGRICULTURAL ACCIDENT INSURANCE IN HOLLAND. Voluntary Compensation Insured in Mutual Associations Favorable Experience. While the insurance against accidents of industrial employees has been compulsory in Holland since March 1st, 1903, the statute has not yet been extended to include accidents occurring in agricultural pur- suits. A project looking to that end was submitted to the Lower House of the Dutch Parliament on April 13th, 1905, but has not yet been en- acted into law. All agricultural workers, cattle growers, nurserymen, florists, market gardeners, keepers of woods and parks and those en- gaged in forestry were to be included in its provisions. No regular wage lists were to be required, but a commission was to determine in each instance the salary of the workmen injured, the total amount of salaries to be charged against the individual employer and the degree of risk incurred by each separate establishment or exploitation. Aside from this, the proposed legislation followed closely the pro- visions of the act covering industrial accidents, and centralized the settlement of claims and the payment of all indemnities in the hands of the State insurance department at Amsterdam. The extension of the accident insurance law so as to cover also agricultural workers is bound to occur before long. The leading agricultural societies have ex- pressed themselves in favor thereof because agricultural laborers, being uninsured and thus discriminated against, are hard to obtain since in- dustrial workmen have obtained the benefit of the accident law. In its original draft of the law of 1903, the authorities planned to make a government monopoly of workingmen's accident insurance and to require all risks to be carried in a central State institution. In order to forestall a like attempt on the part of the government when it comes to include agricultural accidents among those compulsorily insured and to prove that such risks can be economically and satisfactorily taken care of by private organizations, two employers mutual insurance as- sociations have been started. One commenced operations on January 1st, 1909, and insures against accidents in horticultural pursuits only. The second and more important started exactly a year later, and covers all other agricultural accident risks. It was deemed best to separate these two classes, because the accident risk is much lower in horticul- ture and because of the different units of organization to be made use of in the two professions. In horticulture local or regional associations are preferable, while in agriculture associations group themselves best by provinces. Identical in their purpose, namely, to insure employees against the consequences of accidents at the employers' expense, these two associa- tions are organized on the same general lines. Local or provincial as- sociations are formed, each managed by its own board and each hav- ing a number of local committees for controlling and looking after ac- 60 cident cases. The cost of treating all minor accidents is borne by the various provincial associations, which further determine the terms at which members may join and the actual wages paid. The associations can engage in other forms of insurance if they so desire. Each asso- ciation has its board of arbitration, with employers and employees equally represented thereon, to decide disputes as to compensation. Only two disputed cases arose in 1912. These associations, with such affiliated employers as pay salaries in excess of 50,000 florins a year, form and are members of a central asso- ciation, with headquarters in Amsterdam. This central association bears the expense of all serious accidents involving permanent disability or death, thus re-insuring the local associations. The central association also furnishes expert technical advice on the prevention of accidents, on legal and financial questions, and regarding safety regulations. In short, two underlying principles were followed in the formation of these asso- ciations. The first was the greatest possible centralization in every- thing relating to financial administration, both in the interest of economy and also, to make it easier to meet serious losses. The second was the greatest possible decentralization in all matters relating to the treatment and settlement of accidents. To local committees is left the control and determination of the medical treatment and monetary relief. How efficacious and strict a watch is kept over all cases can be judged from the fact that 52,000 laborers insured at the end of 1912 were under the surveillance of 253 separate committees, or one for every 200 employees. Under such conditions, simulation and exaggeration of ac- cidents by the workmen is very difficult. This plan of local committees to supervise accidents is in direct opposition to that provided in the law regarding industrial accidents, under which all matters are controlled and settled from one State head office in Amsterdam. In starting this new system of mutual insurance, many possible adherents were deterred from joining by the inability to determine the cost of the insurance in advance. As all members are proportionately liable for losses, the premiums to be paid could not be limited before- hand, as in the case of insurance by a corporation. To overcome this objection, the estimated premiums for the first year were all paid in full in advance, thus enabling the associations to start with a reserve fund. In consequence it has not been necessary to call on members for any extra contributions. Premiums are high enough to cover a reg- ular addition to the reserve funds as well as expenses and losses, and are levied by the local associations. In turn, they remit to the central body for its expenses. Passing now to the results of this insurance, it should be noted that indemnities paid under it are on the same scale as proposed in the Government's bill for compulsory insurance of agricultural acci- dents. Consequently a fair idea of the risks and cost of such insurance, if made universally obligatory, can be obtained from the operations of these mutual associations. At the end of 1912 they insured one-half of all employees engaged in horticulture and about one-tenth of those in 61 agricultural pursuits. The figures for the two classes of organizations BfcoTr the following results for 1912: Horti- Agri- cultural, cultural. Local associations 40 10 Employers insured 2,464 9,378 Employees insured 12,000 40,000 Wages insured (florins) about 5,000,000 14,000,000 Expenses and losses (florins) 31,381 144,747 Per 100 florins wages 0.65 1.04 Losses 19,013 99,193 Per 100 florins wages 0.40 0.71 Expenses 12,367 48,554 Per 100 florins wages 0.25 0.33 Accidents 220 1,132 Less than 60 days' disability 198 1,030 Over 60 days 19 88 Deaths 3 14 Permanent disability 4 9 Contrasting these results with those in the case of industrial acci- dents, the following comparative figures appear: Horti- Agri- Indus- cultural, cultural. trial. Average premiums 0.75 1.10 2.40 (1907) Accidents per 1,000 workmen 18 28 81 (1911) Deaths & permanent disability per 1,000 0.58 0.57 8.00 (1911) Expenses & losses per 100 florins wages 0.65 1.05 2.22 (1907) In the Dutch mutual associations, premiums and settlements are based on actual payrolls, differing therein from the German system. The payroll system works smoothly and satisfactorily. Owing to the lack of sufficient data, no risk classes have as yet been established. It is intended, however, ultimately to introduce that system. A beginning has been made, of course, in differentiating horticultural from other agri- cultural accidents. Every effort is made to exclude claims for non- occupational accidents, and the strict control and prompt investigation by the local committees tends effectively towards this end. Employers have the option of insuring members of their own household against risks or not as they desire. All but five per cent prefer to have their families covered by the insurance. SWITZERLAND. THE RECENT LEGISLATION REGARDING WORKMEN'S ACCI DENT AND SICKNESS INSURANCE. Good and Weak Points of the Measure Peculiar and Novel Features and Reasons Therefor The Sickness Insurance Law The Accident Insurance Law. Switzerland enjoys the distinction of being one of the first coun- tries to do away with the theory of employers' liability for accidents to employees for negligence only. In 1875 transportation companies were made liable for all accidents to employees, except in case of willful neglect or "Act of God"; and from 1877 on the same principle was gradually extended to apply to work in factories and in building, min- ing and contracting and to other industrial pursuits. Instead of re- maining content with this form of legislation, however, the National Council in 1890 submitted to the voters an amendment to the Federal constitution allowing the introduction of an obligatory system of insur- ance against sickness and accidents. This amendment was ratified on October 12th of the same year by the overwhelming vote of 283,228 for and only 92,200 against. Although the authorities immediately began to work out the details of a new scheme of insurance, the same, known as the Lex Forrer, was not completed until 1898, and only adopted by the National Assembly on October 5th, 1899. Its leading features were the compulsory insurance of workingmen against sickness and accidents; and all classes workmen, artisans, agricultural laborers and small trades-people were made subject to its provisions. Unlike the German compensation laws, wherein the limit is $500, the Forrer Act applied to all those earning up to a thousand dollars a year. Accident insur- ance was to be placed with a state institution, which was to have a monopoly of this branch of the insurance business. The State was to bear one-fifth of the cost of accident insurance and to contribute a certain amount for each person insured against sickness, which con- tributions together would have entailed an estimated cost of eight mil- lion francs. Arrangements were made for the establishment of gov- ernment sickness insurance societies, which would have competed with the existing private societies. That act contained over 200 para- graphs, and its provisions and administrative details were complicated and involved. No sooner was the Lex Forrer enacted than a storm of opposition arose. The existing private sickness insurance societies, with their influential followings, objected to the organization and competition of the public sickness insurance societies therein provided for. The agri- 63 cultural interests claimed that the compulsory insurance of laborers in their industry would impose altogether too heavy a burden. And the industrial classes were opposed to the idea of a government monopoly of accident insurance. A referendum having been demanded by 117,461 voters, the Lex Forrer was submitted to a popular vote on May 20th, 1900, and rejected by a vote of 341,914 against and 148,035 for. Disheartened by this rejection, the Federal Council did not present another bill affecting workingmen's insurance until December 10th, 1906. In its draft of a new measure, the Council was actuated not so much by a desire to frame a perfect statute as by a wish to submit a measure that would receive the approval of the majority of the voters. That motive should be borne in mind in any study of this law. The bill was debated at great length, and was not finally adopted by the National Assembly until June 13th, 1911. Like its predecessor, the Lex Forrer, it aroused great opposition; but this time the objections came mainly from the employer class. With difficulty 75,930 citizens were found who demanded the usual referendum. On February 4th, 1912, the elec- tion took place, preceded by a bitter contest, and the law was finally approved by a vote of 287,585 ayes against 241,416 noes, or by a majority of 46,149. Eight only of the 25 cantons rejected the measure, the most important of them being the French speaking cantons, where the monopolistic features of the new law were strongly disliked for interfering too much with the freedom of the individual. On the other hand, owing to the support of the laboring class, the cantons contain- ing the important manufacturies and industrial workshops approved of the act, as did also those cantons wherein the agricultural interests predominated. The authorities are now busily engaged in preparing the necessary organization to put the new law into effect. That part relat- ing to sickness insurance is expected to go into operation in 1914, and that relating to accidents not later than January 1st, 1916. The Sickness Insurance Law.* While the provisions of the new law relating to accidents aroused great antagonism, those relating to sickness insurance met with com- paratively little opposition or criticism. It has been generally regarded as a step in the right direction, though many persons are of the opinion that it does not go far enough. Before taking up this new statute, a brief survey of the existing system of voluntary sickness insurance is in place. That system has grown rapidly, as the following figures will show: Year. No. societies. Total membership. 1865 632 96,000 1890 1,085 209,920 1903 2,006 505,947 *Title I of Federal Law of June 13, 1911. 64 Out of every 100 inhabitants, 18 are insured against sickness in Ger- many, 13 in Switzerland, 10 in Austria and 7 in France. Next to Ger- many, therefore, where such insurance is compulsory, Switzerland oc- cupies the post of honor. But, while the figures just given make a gratifying showing, every- one familiar with conditions in Switzerland admits that there is a cry- ing need for increasing the scope and efficiency of the present system of sickness insurance. In 1903 it covered only 30% of the male adult population and 7% of the women, only 29% of the men and 21% of the women factory hands being insured. Hardly any children are in- sured; and many perish annually because the parents are unable to pay for proper medical attention. In the remote mountain districts physi- cians are not to be had in the Canton Wallis over half of those who die are without medical attendance. In one extreme case 39 out of the 42 deaths occurring in one community during a given period took place without a doctor being available, even to sign the death certifi- cate. These are grave evils which everyone admits should be remedied as soon as possible. On the part of many of the largest employers of labor, the govern- ment was urged to introduce a system of obligatory sickness insur- ance. Where voluntary insurance prevails, the younger workmen neglect to join, and, handicapped by too large a percentage of older and less healthy members, the societies are often unable to fulfill their obliga- tions. To this fact is ascribed the failure of 31% of all the Swiss sick- ness insurance societies during the period 1880-1903. In the various trades and occupations wherein the employer is now made responsible for all accidents, only one-half of all the workmen are insured against sickness. As only a limited number are injured in accidents, whereas all laborers sooner or later meet with sickness, compulsory sickness in- surance forms the foundation for any universal and satisfactory sys- tem of social insurance. However sound these arguments, the authorities felt that the decisive vote by which the Lex Forrer was rejected proved conclusively that the Swiss people did not desire as yet the introduction of a system of compulsory sickness insurance. As the next best thing therefore, the government decided on the plan followed in Sweden, Denmark and Bel- gium of encouraging the growth and extension of voluntary sickness societies by a system of subsidies. But, in order to expedite introduc- tion of compulsory sickness insurance, permission is granted in the new law to the individual cantons and communes to declare sickness insur- ance compulsory, either for all or for certain categories only, of work- men, such as the more poorly paid. If a canton makes such insurance obligatory and defrays part of the expenses, the Federal government agrees to contribute an amount equal to one-third of the total outlay by the canton. It is impossible to say as yet whether any of the communes or cantons will avail themselves of this right. Under the new law all existing Swiss sickness societies irrespective of religious, political or other entrance requirements for members 65 may become approved or recognized societies and thereby entitled to government aid. They must not be run for profit, must show their financial responsibility, must be open to both sexes and must receive Swiss on as favorable terms as members of any other nationality. Their rules and regulations, as well as all proposed changes, must first be approved by the government authorities. The societies must agree to receive members of a year's standing coming from other societies, who desire to transfer their membership on account of removal, change of occupation or dissolution of the original society. To obtain govern- ment aid, the societies must either furnish medical attendance and medicines or pay their members a sickness benefit of at least one franc a day. As a preventive of simulation, children under 14 years of age cannot be insured in societies which give sickness benefits. For the same reason, the sickness benefit is payable only from the third day of illness, whereas medical treatment must be given from the first day. As the period of disability is apt to be less where the ailing member has to shoulder a part of the cost of medical treatment, the societies are obliged to bear only three-fourths of such cost where the time of treat- ment in any given twelve months aggregates 270 days or more. But the societies are required, if they so elect, to give members only 180 days of treatment in the course of one year. Besides the matters just mentioned, the societies must undertake to treat for the account of the accident funds all accident cases for the first six weeks of disability, subject to reimbursement and appropriate remuneration. In addition, they must forego the right of selecting physicians as heretofore, and must accept the services of any doctor, chosen by any ailing member, who resides in the locality, and who is willing to serve at the rate of compensation prescribed by the govern- ment. Up to the present time, women have had comparatively little oppor- tunity of insuring themselves against sickness. Of the sickness societies existing in 1903, 58% accepted men only as members, for the reason that women are a more dangerous risk. Although not so frequently ill, they are apt to be longer sick than in the case of the other sex, and there has been a decided prejudice against admitting them as members of sickness societies. In prescribing, therefore, that no woman may hereafter be excluded on account of her sex from any recognized society the new law makes a great step forward. Nor can she be required to pay any higher dues than a man she is put on a plane of equality. Although the same disability results as in the case of an ordinary illness, only a few of the Swiss sickness societies have furnished sick benefits or medical treatment in the event of childbirth. Hereafter, however, the accepted sickness societies are obliged to treat all such cases as though they were ordinary illnesses, and must give assistance or treatment for a minimum period of six weeks. And as experience has shown that children have a much better chance of surviving if nursed by their mothers for the first few months of their existence, the so- cieties are obliged to pay all mothers who nurse their children for a 66 period of at least ten weeks from time of birth a special grant of twenty francs. In this way it is hoped to do much in the way of dimin- ishing the rate of infant mortality. If 300,000 women are insured in the approved sickness societies, which is the number the authorities have calculated upon, 18,000 cases of childbirth are expected to occur among them each year. Whenever a sickness society shall have fulfilled the necessary re- quirements, it becomes entitled to an annual subsidy or contribution from the central government, based on its membership. The amount of this contribution varies. For children in all cases S 1 /^ francs, and the same amount for the male members of such societies as pay either benefits of at least 1 franc a day or furnish medical attendance. In the case of women members, 4 francs is contributed, because their ratio of risk is higher. Societies supplying both benefits and treatment are to receive 5 francs a member, the sexes being treated alike, and 50 cen- times extra is paid in all cases where in the course of 540 days, 360 days of treatment are allowed. Twenty francs is allowed for every case of childbirth, and the same sum in addition for each newly born child nursed by its mother for a period of ten weeks. But the sum total of the government's contribution in any given year is not to exceed two- thirds of the gross amount realized from members' dues, gifts and other sources. And where cantons or communes have made sickness insurance obligatory either for all or for only certain portions of the laboring population and have assumed the payment of the dues of members, either in whole or in part, the Federal government is to contribute one-third of any amount thus expended. Specially favored treatment is accorded the remote and thinly populated mountain districts, with limited means of communication. Here the total of the Government's contribution may reach 7 francs per mem- ber per year; and it may also make a special grant of 3 francs per head to the cantons or communes in order to reduce the cost of treating sick persons. In 1903 there were 505,947 persons insured in the various private sickness societies. After the new law has gone into full effect, the of- ficials count on a membership of 800,000 in accepted sickness societies entitled to benefits under the act; 660,000 in voluntary societies and 140,000 in societies in cantons and communes wherein sickness insurance shall have been made obligatory. The Government's sickness insurance budget is therefore estimated in detail as follows: Voluntary Insurance Societies. 100,000 children, at fr. 3% fr. 350,00 255,000 men, at fr. 3% " 892,500 70,000 women, at f r. 4 " 280,000 235,000 men and women, at f r. 5 " 1,175,000 400,000 extra treatment, at fr. 0.50 " 200,000 14,000 births, at f r. 20 " 280,000 4,700 nursing mothers, at f r. 20 " 94,000 Total fr. 3,271,500 Compulsory Insurance Societies. 140,000 members, at fr. 4 (contributions to cantons) fr. 560,000 35,000 members at fr. 2 (cantons assuming dues of needy persons) " 70,000 2,800 births, at fr. 20 " 56,000 700 nursing mothers, at fr. 20 " 18,000 Total fr. 704,000 For societies in mountainous districts " 500,000 Grand total fr. 4,475,500 Based on the figures expended by the societies in 1903, the cost of providing 800,000 persons with benefits and treatment in sickness would be about seventeen million francs. The Government's contribu- tion, therefore, will be slightly more than one-fourth of the total amount required certainly a very generous proportion. An enrollment of 800,- 000 would mean that about 21% of the total population would be pro- tected by sickness insurance, which percentage is about the same as that in Germany. But will the existing societies accept the Government requirements ? As we have seen, the new law has many good points. It does away with all discrimination against women and enables them to obtain in- surance on the same terms as men. Medical assistance is granted them in case of childbirth. A very important provision is that allowing the transfer of membership from one society to another where a laborer changes his place of occupation, for 100,000 such transfers are said to occur annually in Switzerland. The way is left open for the gradual introduction by the individual cantons of compulsory sickness insurance for all classes, while especial care has been bestowed on the formation of sickness insurance societies in the remote mountain districts. The widespread and successful application of this law depends, however, largely on the extent to which societies can be found to conform to the Government requirements, so as to become entitled to the Federal subsidies. As far as the existing societies are concerned, there are several provisions in the law which may cause a number of them to hesitate about accepting its terms. In the first place, the societies must give up their independence of action and subject themselves to Government inspection and regula- tion. Many of them are supported to a considerable degree by con- tributions from employers, etc., which will be lost in the event of 68 change to accepted Government organizations. No longer will they be able to keep down medical costs and to guard against simulation by having members treated by trustworthy physicians of their own selec- tion. Lastly, which is the most serious objection, they may get into grave financial difficulties by being obliged to treat for the state insti- tution all accident cases for the first six weeks of disability, and to advance the compensation therefor at the rate of 80% of wages, instead of about one franc a day, as in the case of sickness. The Government agrees, of course, to reimburse the societies according to a fixed tariff for the handling of such accident cases; but whether that tariff will suffice to cover the additional outlays made in this connection remains to be seen. It should be noted, however, that under the law any accepted so- ciety can cease to act as such by giving three months' notice of such intention. In view of this provision, it is safe to assume that the ma- jority of the existing sickness societies will elect at the outset to be- come accepted Government institutions. Later on, if they find the burdens and annoyances of acting as such to be too heavy, doubtless a number of them will take advantage of this loophole in the law and give notice of their desire to resume their former voluntary, uncontrolled and unassisted form. To what extent such withdrawals will take place it would be futile to speculate in advance. The Accident Insurance Law.* The new law establishes a National Swiss Accident Insurance De- partment, with headquarters at Lucerne and individual agencies i[n each canton, governed! by an administrative council of 40 members appointed by the Federal Council for a term of six years. Twelve of them are to be representatives of the compulsorily insured employees and sixteen of the same class of employers, four are to be named as representatives of the voluntarily insured and eight as representatives of the Government. The active management is to be in the hands of a board of managers nominated by the Administrative Council, but elected by the members of the Federal Assembly, who are not bound, however, to follow the recommendations of the Administrative Council. Four branches of insurance are to be undertaken by the National Insurance Department. First, compulsory occupational accident insur- ance affecting all workmen employed in Switzerland in the following oc- cupations: Railway and steamboat services; postoffice employees; those engaged in factories subject to the provisions of the law of March 23, 1877; in the building trades; transportation by land or water; the erec- tion and repairing of telephone and telegraph lines and machinery; in- stallations of a technical nature; general contracting, tunnelling, mining, *Title II of Federal Law of June 13, 1911. fThis body is really more advisory than governmental; see infra. 69 quarrying, and the building of streets, bridges, waterworks and sewers. The premiums for this insurance have to be paid by the employers. Second in the list is a decided innovation, namely, compulsory in- surance in the trades and occupations just enumerated against non-occu- pational accidents or such as occur outside of working hours. Here one-fourth of the premium is charged to the Federal Government and the other three-fourths to the employee. The employer is to advance the workman's share of such premium, and may deduct the amount of the same from his wages. A third category covers voluntary insurance up to 3,000 francs, against accidents to persons not included among the obligatorily insured, residing in Switzerland and over 14 years of age. One-eighth of the premium required in such cases is to be advanced by the Government. Lastly comes the voluntary insurance of employers against liability for injuries to outside or third persons. In these two last branches, the Government institution will be ex- posed to the competition of the private insurance companies, but on equal terms only in the last class, for in the field of voluntary self- insurance the private companies will be badly handicapped and will be at a great disadvantage through the Federal Government's donation of one-eighth of the required premium. Besides endowing the department with a working capital of five million francs* and a reserve fund of the same amount, the Govern- ment is to pay one-half of all the administrative costs of the central institution and to allow it the free use of the mails and exemption from all taxation except on real property not made use of in its insurance business. A certain part of the premiums are to be set aside in each of the four projected branches of insurance as a reserve until such time as the fund shall equal one-half of the average premium receipts plus the Government subsidy received by the institution during the last preceding five years. The authorities are empowered to compel the societies subsidized by the Government under the sickness insurance law to treat all accident cases for the State institution's account for a maximum period of six weeks. Only from five to ten per cent of all injuries caused by acci- dents remain unhealed or uncured at the end of that period; and spe- cial arrangements will have to be made for those cases. Compensation under the new law is to be granted on a liberal scale. Besides free medical treatment, the injured party is entitled, from the third day on, to 80% of the wages earned by him before the accident. In every case, 14 francs is taken as the maximum daily wage any- thing in excess of that figure is disregarded. If permanent disability ensues, 70% of his customary wages is to be paid, but 4,000 francs is to be considered the maximum salary in calculating the rate. If only partial permanent disability ensues, the amount is reduced in propor- *This donation to the working capital, however, is simply an advance to be repaid. 70 tion to the extent of the injury received. In case of death, a funeral benefit of 40 francs is provided for, and the widow is to receive during her widowhood an annuity equal to 30% of her husband's yearly wages. Children each receive 15% until they are 16; if orphans, 25%. If a child is permanently incapacitated at the age of 16, the annuity does not cease, but runs until the 70th year. Ascendants receive for life, and brothers and sisters up to the age of 16, an annuity equal to 20% of the annual wage. But in no case of survivorship is more than 60% paid if an excess results, the annuities are scaled down, each propor- tionally, to 60%. The widow and children are preferred for the amounts due them, but if they aggregate less than 60% the ascendants and collateral heirs receive the difference. Where the annuity to sur- vivors, or that granted to the victim for permanent partial disability, is less than 10 francs a month, the State institution has the right to com- pound it by the payment of a lump sum. Foreigners, (of whom 200,000 are estimated to be working in Switzerland), receive only % of the benefits accorded to natives, unless their home country grants to Swiss* citizens equally as high a com- pensation in case of accident or sickness, as is to be provided by the Swiss law. Under the present employers' liability system, an injured workman, if only temporarily disabled, is entitled to recover the full amount of wages lost by him. In granting only 80% of the daily wage earned in such cases, the new law operates to the disadvantage of the em- ployee. In case of death or permanent disability, however, he will receive a much higher rate of compensation than now. Instead of a maximum recovery of 6,000 francs, the amount to be awarded is an annuity equal to 60% to 70% respectively of his former wages, up to 4,000 francs annually. 6,000 francs capitalized at 4% will yield an income of only 240 francs a year, which is the highest amount an employee can now recover. But hereafter, the average yearly annuity paid will vary between 60% and 70% of 1,200 francs (the average yearly wage), i. e., will be between 720 and 840 francs. Thus a per- manently disabled workman will be three times better off than under the present system. According to the calculation of the authorities, 700,000 persons are counted upon to become insured against accidents. This number is made up as follows: 51,000 Railway and steamboat employees. 377,000 Employees covered by present employers' liability insurance. 122,000 Employees additional in compulsorily insured list. 150,000 Employees voluntarily insured . 700,000 Total number. At an arerage wage of 1,200 francs, this would make a total pay r 71 roll of 840 million francs. The premium rate is figured as follows: For occupational accidents 2.75 For non-occupational accidents 55 For administration expenses 33 Total 3.63 Based on the premium rate and total pay roll just mentioned, the cost of this new insurance will amount to 30,492,000 francs. This is to be divided as follows: Per cent, of Wages. Employers, 19,008,000 francs 2.26 Employees, 8,320,500 francs 99 Government, 3,163,500 francs 38 The employers have to bear the entire cost of insurance against ordinary occupational accidents, less the Government's contribution to- wards the estimated administrative expenses. The employee's share is divided as follows: Francs. % cost of non-occupational accidents of the com- pulsorily insured 2,871,000 % cost of occupational accidents of the volun- tarily insured 4,539,500 % cost of non-occupational accidents of volun- tarily insured 910,000 Total 8,320,500 The Government's contribution is apportioned as follows: Francs ^4 cost of non-occupational accidents of the com- pulsorily insured 957,000 % cost of occupational accidents of voluntar- ily insured 648,500 % cost of non-occupational accidents of volun- tarily insured 130,000 % cost of administration expenses 1,428,000 Total 3,163,500 To this should be added the cost of the special insurance tribu- nals, viz: 161,000 francs, which brings the Government's total esti- mated outlay up to 3,324,500 francs. If to this be added 4,475,500 francs to be bestowed on the sickness insurance department, the Swiss 72 Government is facing an anticipated annual expenditure all told of 7,800,000 francs on account of its new insurance law. On behalf of the new law one can say that it will bring about compulsory accident insurance for one-fourth more employees than under present conditions. To the severely injured workman it affords a much higher compensation, given in the form of a permanent annuity instead of by the payment of an easily dissipated lump sum. The average rate of indemnity is higher than that granted in any other country. Even non-occupational accidents, or those outside of working hours, are to be compulsorily insured, something that has never yet been attempted in any other country. Whether as many as 150,000 will become voluntarily insured, is an open question. Even though the Government assumes one-eighth of the total cost, the em- ployees, especially in the more poorly paid occupations, like agri- cultural pursuits, may find it beyond their means to pay the remain- ing seven-eighths of the high premiums required. As compared with those in the obligatorily insured categories, those taking out voluntary insurance are at a decided disadvantage. The former obtain insurance against every kind of accident and only have to defray % of the premium for non-occupational accidents, amounting to 0.041 2-3 of the total wage earned. To obtain the same protection, the voluntarily insured must pay the entire premium, less only the Government's Vs share and its contribution to the cost of adminis- trative expenses. For them the premium charge works out over 3% of the total yearly wage. If insurance against non-occupational acci- dents had been left optional, one-sixth of this charge could have been saved; and no good reason exists why this should not have been done. But the authorities preferred to have the two classes of insurance go together both occupational and non-occupational insurance must be taken out, or the worker not compulsorily insured will get none at all. From nearly every point of view the insurance of non-occupational accidents appears to have been a mistaken move. It is right and proper to insure workmen against the consequences of accidents arising in the course of their employment, but to go a step further and to indemnify them against injuries incurred while not working and while under no professional risk is to put them in a favored class as compared with the rest of the population. As no other country except Sweden, where the Government furnishes such insurance but only on a voluntary basis has attempted to insure such risks, no reliable statistics are available as to the cost. Its financial consequences are therefore altogether un- certain. If, in spite of unremitting watchfulness, simulation is constantly on the increase in occupational accidents to workingmen, how are such fraudulent practices to be checked or controlled where injuries are re- ported to have occurred away from all oversight or witnesses ? Will not, therefore, the estimate of 13% of all accidents be greatly ex- ceeded? The experience of the Swiss insurance company, The Helvetia, need only be recalled, which company undertook such insurance, but was speedily obliged to give it up on account of the losses entailed due 73 to artificially inflicted or simulated injuries. The workmen of Italian nationality were especially noted for self-made wounds, produced by acids and corrosives. Another interesting problem is whether the employers will not sooner or later assume the employees' quota of the premiums for non- occupational accidents, in which event all check upon simulation from the employees' self-interest will be lost. That this will come to pass is pre- dicted by many in touch with the situation. By the terms of the law, the employer is obliged to remit to the Federal insurance department the portion of the premiums due from his employees for non-occupational ac- cident insurance. Where an employee is earning merely a minimum liv- ing wage he cannot shoulder this amount, small though it be, and it must perforce be borne by his employer. In the larger and more pros- perous establishments, the employers will do this for all classes of em- ployees rather than be bothered with the annoyance of having to keep a complicated set of books and of deducting the small sum of a few cents a week from the wages of each workman. And in time the smaller em- ployers may follow suit. As is no secret, undesirable concessions and unnatural compromises were made in order to secure the passage of the accident insurance law. To this circumstance is due the insertion and retention of the provision for the insurance of non-occupational accidents. The Lex Forrer, so overwhelmingly rejected in 1900, contained a like provision, advocated on the ground of the difficulty in distinguishing between these and the usual run of occupational accidents. On its being shown that in the case of 280,000 accidents settled by the three leading Swiss employers' liability insurance companies, only 16 lawsuits arose to determine the category in which the accident belonged, the retention of the non-occu- pational accident clause was then urged on the ground that for the in- jured workman the consequences of an accident incurred outside of working hours were just as disastrous as in the case of one received in the course of his employment. That is doubtless true. But why should the State be called upon to help protect a certain class of its population only at the expense of the rest against the results of ac- cidents incurred through causes common to all classes, and in no way due to the risks of their employment? Besides its unfairness to the remainder of the community, the in- clusion of the non-occupational accident clause is responsible for the rise of 14% in the estimated cost of the new law as compared with the acts heretofore in force. If that clause had been omitted the employers would have been able to shoulder the entire cost and no contribution from the workmen would have been necessary. The Federal Govern- ment would have been relieved from the burden of granting subsidies to carry out its scheme of accident insurance, which nearly every other nation that has legislated on the subject has thus far succeeded in avoiding. The money thus saved might have been used in starting a system of old age insurance. In spite of all these possibilities, the Na- tional Assembly, influenced by political considerations, resolutely stuck 74 to its determination to include non-occupational accidents within the scope of the law. Otherwise the influential Socialist party threatened that they would vote against the measure; and it was realized that with- out its support the act could not obtain the support of a majority of the electorate. It should also be noted that the Government's being obliged, owing to the inclusion of non-occupational accidents, to grant subsidies for accident insurance, was one of the principal reasons urged for intro- ducing a State monopoly of accident insurance. Another section of the law which has been much criticised is that relating to the compensation of foreigners. Its wording is unfortunate in providing that foreigners are only to receive three-fourths of the usual compensation, except those from countries wherein Swiss are paid as high an indemnity as they would have received if injured at home. But such a case is never likely to occur, inasmuch as the Swiss law grants a much higher rate of compensation than that afforded by any other country 25% more than Germany, which is the next highest. If the section had read that foreigners, whose countries indemnified work- men of Swiss nationality as liberally as native citizens, should receive full instead of three-quarters compensation, other nations would have been under some incentive to treat injured Swiss laborers as liberally as their own subjects. To make full compensation to foreigners em- ployed in Switzerland dependent on other countries raising their com- pensation rates to the high Swiss standard, is seeking the impossible. Consequently this provision of the law will fail of its object and will accomplish nothing towards doing away with any existing discrimina- tions against Swiss laborers in foreign countries. Much stress has been laid by the advocates of the law on the fact that the central government insurance establishment is to be rim on mutual lines. In effect, it is claimed, the institution should be likened to a large mutual insurance company managed by those directly inter- ested. The appointment of the members of the governing board, how- ever, is vested in the National Assembly, and, with eight direct repre- sentatives of the Federal Government thereon, the authorities are pretty certain to control the policy of the insurance department. Besides, 40 governors is altogether too cumbersome a board to work efficiently, and the real management and control of policy will be in the hands of th directors, whom the National Assembly can select as it chooses. The Government office is expected to begin operations with a staff of from 500 to 600 clerks. As has been stated before, the unhappy insertion for vote getting purposes of compulsory insurance against non-occupational accidents, with its attendant Government subsidy, was one of the chief causes why a State accident insurance department was deemed necessary. The other reason urged for its establishment, that the Government would furnish through its central institution insurance most cheaply and satis- factorily does not appear well founded. Even the advocates of a Government system have had to admit that the existing private agencies stock companies, mutual societies, and 75 employers' associations have covered this field of insurance eco- nomically and given a very satisfactory service. The average profits of the 17 domestic and foreign stock companies directly insuring em- ployers liability risks have only equalled 1% of the total premium re- ceipts such insurance being given at cost price. The largest and strongest company of them all (the Zurich) showed for the period 1906-1910 gross premium receipts of 159 million francs and net profits of 12,700,000 francs. Of these only 2,200,000 francs came from surplus earnings, while 10,500,000 francs were derived from interest on th* legal reserves carried. In 1910, the two leading companies (the Zurich and the Winterthur) showed, the former a profit of 218,000 and the lat- ter a loss of 213,000 francs, after paying all losses and administrative expenses. Had it not been for the interest on the large reserves ac- cumulated of 2,706,000 and 1,803,000 francs, respectively, the companies would not have been able to declare a dividend. Claims are settled quickly and satisfactorily and with almost no litigation. Out of a total of 103,000 accidents settled during the course of two years by the different Swiss private organizations, only 165 were taken into court, or less than two lawsuits per 1,000 accidents. In contrast to this, one need only think of the enormous and constantly increasing mass of liti- gation in Germany and Austria. In Austria there is one appeal for about every three accidents entitling the injured to compensation. In 1909 76,352 appeals, or 18% of all accident cases, were brought before the German arbitration tribunals, and 25,234 of these, or 33%, were further appealed to the imperial insurance office. On account of the excellent record made by the Swiss companies, it is all the more sur- prising that the National Assembly should have decided on suppressing their activities in the accident insurance field. In favor thereof the argument was advanced that, if allowed to compete, the private com- panies would take only the better class of business, leaving the state institution to handle all the bad risks. Even if that were so, it is im- material, for the state can charge what rates it pleases and thereby recoup itself for any losses. As a matter of fact, the Zurich and Winter- thur companies formally offered to share any and all risks with the state institution on an equal basis. Nevertheless, the Swiss lawmakers, perhaps fearing that the government institution could neither flourish nor make headway unless it had the field to itself, remained unmoved and determined to do away with all private competition. Aside from the possible heavy cost of non-professional accidents, it remains to be seen whether the intended government monopoly of work- men's accident insurance is going to work reasonably well in practice or prove a very costly experiment. State insurance has usually resulted either in excessively high premium rates, with costs covered, or in too low premiums, with constantly recurring deficits. That the new government accident insurance department will furnish insurance cheaper or settle claims more promptly than the private com- panies is not to be expected. Whatever experience there is, points the other way. The history of the government's military insurance depart- 76 ment against sickness and accidents, where costs have been rising by leaps and bounds during its 10-year existence and have averaged more than five times the original amount estimated, is far from re-assuring. Complaint is made of the dilatoriness and of the disagreeable haggling of the government officials in settling with victims of railway accidents occurring on the lines owned by the state. In view of this, both employers and employees may hereafter have decided cause to regret in many respects the suppression of the existing system of private competition and its replacement by a bureaucratic government monopoly. SWISS EXPERIENCE IN MILITARY INSURANCE. An Instructive Ten Year Test of State Insurance Unfavorable Ex- perience. As throwing some light on the subject of State insurance, th* operations during the last ten years of the government bureau for in- suring those engaged in military service is not without interest. Beginning in a small way in 1874, the Swiss government thereafter gradually extended the relief offered to those who become ill or dis- abled while in the military service. During the period 1889-1894, the State insured such military risks in one of the larger private Swiss insurance companies with very satisfactory results, as was frankly stated in the National Assembly. Nevertheless, the officials came to the conclusion that it was undignified for the government to employ a private agency, and, from 1895 on, conducted this branch of insurance for account of the government direct. In 1898 a new proposal was made to increase the rate of compensa- tion to be paid to soldiers, who suffered injury or incurred sickness or disability during the time of their military service, to the same amount that an industrial establishment would have to pay to one of its em- ployees in like circumstances. The advocates of the measure asserted that, based on the most careful estimates, the increased cost of this extra insurance would not exceed 100,000 francs a year. In place of an annual average outlay of 64,000 francs, the government experts confidently predicted that 164,000 francs would suffice to meet all charges in the course of the year under the proposed act. Accordingly, on these representations, the Swiss Parliament adopted the proposed law; and it took effect January 1st, 1902. Hardly had the new law gone into operation before it was seen that the estimates of its cost were absolutely untrustworthy and too low. In the very first year after its passage, an extra credit of 500,000 francs had to be voted, in addition to the 165,000 francs provided in the gov- ernment budget. How far the authorities erred in the figures they submitted, namely, 165,000 francs, is best shown by the following table of the actual cost of the insurance of the Swiss military establishment for the 10-year period beginning with January 1st, 1902. Insurance cost. 1902 fr. 680,000 1908 fr. 850,000 1903 " 807,000 1909 " 893,000 1904 " 787,000 1910 " 1,017,000 1905 " 836,000 1911 " 1,316,000 1906 " 879,000 Average " 894,000 1907 " 876,000 In the original government estimate, the sum of 116,500 franen 7i waa deemed sufficient to meet all payments required on account of ac- cident or disability cases. The actual average amount required for the 10-year period has proved to be 351,000 francs, the least in any girea year being 220,000 francs and the highest (in 1911) being 607,000 francs. In the department of sickness insurance, the showing is even worse. In place of an anticipated annual outlay of 36,000 francs, the amount expended has run beyond that required for disability cases and in 1911 reached the total of 614,000 francs. Administration costs have likewise far exceeded the original estimates and show a steady in- crease from year to year, having risen from 33,000 francs in 1902 to 69,000 in 1911. Most of these figures are clearly set forth in a message dated No- vember 12th, 1912, addressed by the Bundesrat, or governing council, to the Swiss National Assembly. The increased cost is ascribed in part to the higher indemnity rates paid under the new law, which have induced more of the well-to-do soldiers to apply for relief than was the case with the small amounts previously doled out, and secondly, to the simulation and exaggeration of illnesses and accidents. Thus the gov- ernment counted on having to issue only 20 permanent pensions a year, instead of which the average number has been 53. In one year, the figure rose to 129. In the last 12 months before this law took ef- fect, 2,908 cases of sickness were reported, entailing 47,010 days of illness, whereas in 1911 the corresponding figures were 5,906 cases and 109,474 days. Whatever may be the true causes for its unexpected and costly re- sults, the experience of the government in the branch of military in- surance makes a very unfavorable showing. The losses to be met proved from the start to be four times as great as had been counted on, and are constantly rising although the size of the army has remained about the same. Simulation of illnesses and exaggeration of injuries are rife; and the officials are unable to make any headway against these abuses. This chapter of Swiss State insurance has only added to the misgivings of those who so strongly opposed the introduction of the system of compulsory accident insurance to be carried on by the State alone without any outside competition. Will the State make a better showing when it comes to handling this new class of risks or will the outcome be as similarly unfortunate and costly for the govern- ment finances as in the case of the insurance granted to those in its military service? This is a question which must be left to time and experience for an answer. Photomount Pamphlet Binder Gaylord Bros. Makers Stockton, Calif. PAT. JAN. 21. 1908 678980 7 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY