y of California 
 rn Regional 
 ry Facility
 
 LIBRARY 
 
 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA 
 RIVERSIDE
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION
 
 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY 
 
 NEW YORK BOSTON CHICAGO 
 ATLANTA SAN FRANCISCO 
 
 MACMILLAN & CO., LIMITED 
 
 LONDON BOMBAY CALCUTTA 
 MELBOURNE 
 
 THE MACMILLAN CO. OF CANADA, LTD. 
 
 TORONTO
 
 IP 
 
 ESSAYS 
 
 IN 
 
 MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 JOHN A. FA ) IRLIE, PH.D. 
 
 PROFESSOR OF ADMINISTRATIVE LAW IN THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 
 ADTHOR OF "THE CENTRALIZATION OF ADMINISTRATION IN NEW 
 YORK STATE," "MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION," "NATIONAL 
 ADMINISTRATION OF THE UNITED STATES," " LOCAL GOV- 
 ERNMENT IN COUNTIES, TOWNS, AND VILLAGES," ETC. 
 
 Nefo ff otfc 
 
 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY 
 1908 
 
 All rights reserved
 
 fa 
 
 COPTBIOHT, 1908, 
 
 BT THE MACMILLAN COMPANY. 
 
 Set up and electrotyped. Published January, 1908. 
 
 Norfoooto 
 
 J. 8. Gushing Co. Berwick A> Smith Co. 
 Norwood, Mass., U.S.A.
 
 PREFACE 
 
 THIS volume of essays does not profess to be in any sense 
 a systematic and comprehensive discussion of municipal 
 government. It is a series of papers and articles on special 
 topics that have been prepared under varying circumstances 
 and for different purposes ; and under these conditions they 
 show considerable variety in method of treatment. But it 
 is believed that some readers concerned in municipal ques- 
 tions will find it convenient to have these essays collected 
 together where they may be made more readily available. 
 
 In arranging the essays an attempt has been made to 
 group those most closely related. In the first group are 
 those relating to problems of organization and the legal 
 relation of cities to the state. In the second group are those 
 dealing with municipal functions and activities. The third 
 group presents some observations on municipal government 
 in Europe made during a visit in the year 1906. And the 
 last essay, on Instruction in Municipal Government, stands 
 in a class by itself. 
 
 Most of these articles have been previously published in 
 various magazines and journals, or delivered before several 
 societies. My thanks are due to the editors of these jour- 
 nals and the officers of the societies for permission to reprint 
 in this volume. More specific acknowledgments will be 
 found in the footnotes at the beginning of each article. 
 Many of these articles have been revised, and a few have 
 been largely rewritten in order to include the record of later 
 events. One paper on the Revenue Systems of American 
 and European Cities is the joint work of Professor Charles 
 E. Merriam, of the University of Chicago, and myself.
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 PAOX 
 
 I. SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT ... 1 
 II. PROBLEMS OF AMERICAN CITY GOVERNMENT FROM THE 
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE POINT OF VIEW .... 11 
 
 III. THE RELATION OF CIVIL SERVICE REFORM TO MUNI- 
 
 CIPAL ADMINISTRATION 39 
 
 IV. MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES ... 48 
 V. THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 95 
 
 VI. MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST . . . 110 
 
 VII. AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS .... 125 
 
 VIH. RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS IN 
 
 THE UNITED STATES 145 
 
 IX. PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION IN AMERICAN CITIES 164 
 
 X. REVENUE SYSTEMS OF AMERICAN AND FOREIGN CITIES 173 
 
 XL MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT . . 219 
 
 XII. THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO . . 230 
 
 XIII. SOME CONSIDERATIONS ON MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF 
 
 PUBLIC UTILITIES 262 
 
 XIV. COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS .... 275 
 
 XV. MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN . . . 287 
 
 XVI. MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN SOME EUROPEAN CITIES . 303 
 
 XVII. MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA .... 316 
 
 XVIII. MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY .... 330 
 
 XIX. INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT . . . 350 
 INDEX 361 
 
 vii
 
 I 
 
 SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 1 
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT is so large and so complicated a 
 subject that when one is asked to speak on the broad general 
 topic, it is no easy matter to decide what aspect to discuss. 
 There are the exciting and dramatic events of municipal 
 politics in particular cities; there are the difficult legal 
 problems of municipal organization and the relation of cities 
 to the state government ; and there are a long series of special 
 subjects connected with the everyday work of municipal 
 officials. Instead of considering any of these subjects, how- 
 ever, I shall attempt here simply to emphasize the general 
 importance of municipal government by a brief sketch of the 
 development of cities and their functions, with some reference 
 to the defects of American municipal management and means 
 of improving the situation. 
 
 By municipal government is meant the local government 
 in cities; and it should be of some interest at the outset to 
 note the rapid recent development of cities as the fundamental 
 fact in making the problems of their government of vital con- 
 cern. Cities have existed since the earliest period of recorded 
 history; and even large cities developed in ancient times 
 especially during the time of the Roman Empire, when there 
 were several of over half a million population, while Rome 
 itself had at least a million. But with the decline of the 
 Roman Empire, cities also declined; and although at the 
 end of the mediaeval period there was a brilliant revival of 
 city life, notably in Italy and Germany, the cities of that 
 time by no means equalled those of antiquity. Beginning, 
 however, in England about the middle of the eighteenth 
 
 1 Revised from an address delivered at Ann Arbor in 1902. 
 B 1
 
 2 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 century, the growth of cities both in number and in size assumed 
 a rapid and accelerating rate. Spreading to other countries, 
 especially hi Europe and America, this new movement by the 
 early part of the nineteenth century easily surpassed that 
 of the Roman period. Increasing by its own momentum, 
 the process has continued and is continuing until one almost 
 fears to consider its future possibilities. A hundred years 
 ago there were in all Europe less than a score of cities with 
 over 100,000 population, and not one such city in America. 
 To-day there are two hundred cities of this size in Europe 
 and America. The total population in cities of this class has 
 increased from 4^ to 60 millions, and from less than 3 per cent 
 to one-eighth of the total. At the beginning of the nineteenth 
 century there were less than two hundred cities of over 
 10,000 population in all the civilized world ; and their aggre- 
 gate population was but 10 millions, less than 6 per cent of 
 the total. To-day, such cities are to be counted by the 
 thousand Great Britain and the United States have each 
 nearly five hundred and their aggregate population is 
 more than 100 millions, or over one-fifth of the total 
 in the civilized countries. In 1800 not a single city in the 
 world was known to have over a million inhabitants. At 
 present, there are nine such in Europe and America, and 
 four others in Asia. 
 
 This increase in urban communities and urban population 
 which even our strongest adjectives fail fitly to characterize 
 has meant much more than a corresponding increase in the 
 work and importance of municipal government. The growth 
 of these dense masses of compact population has not merely 
 increased the old lines of municipal activity; it has brought 
 about new conditions which demanded the exercise of new 
 functions to make life in the cities even as satisfactory as 
 life in the country. It has also brought the opportunity and 
 the means for developing still other lines of activity impos- 
 sible in rural communities which add to the comfort and 
 convenience of life, and permit of further progress in the
 
 SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 3 
 
 arts of civilization. Other factors have also come into play. 
 The progress of scientific knowledge and its application has 
 opened the way to further fields of municipal action. The 
 influence of democratic ideas and the humanizing spirit has 
 promoted still more additions to municipal functions, so that 
 the masses of the population may share in the social, intel- 
 lectual, and aesthetic aspects of life, hitherto confined to the 
 well-to-do. These causes have indeed broadened and deep- 
 ened the scope of all forms of governmental action; but 
 especially within the cities has the work of the municipal 
 authorities expanded with stupendous increments, far beyond 
 even the startling development of cities and city population. 
 
 Look for a few moments in broad outline at the duties and 
 activities which engage the energies of a modern municipal 
 government. In the first place are the protective functions 
 of maintaining peace, order, and health. These are, it is true, 
 also primary duties of the state governments through their legis- 
 lative statutes and systems of judicial courts. But the en- 
 forcement of the laws and the operation of the courts depend 
 in large part on the efficiency of the municipal police, while 
 urban conditions demand local regulations for the public 
 safety not covered by the general laws of the state. So we 
 find in our cities that the old night watchman with his staff 
 and bell has given way to the organized, uniformed, and 
 disciplined police force of a quasi-military character. For 
 the protection of property from the dangers of fire, the 
 volunteer company with its hand buckets has been supplanted 
 by the paid brigade of disciplined men equipped with a host 
 of mechanical appliances. The prevention and suppression 
 of contagious diseases is intrusted to scientifically trained 
 health officers, aided in larger cities by corps of expert assist- 
 ants also trained in the details of sanitary science. 
 
 But municipal governments of to-day do vastly more than 
 this protective work of warding off danger from the citizens. 
 They enter aggressively on large fields of labor which add 
 positively to the convenience, comfort, and well-being of the
 
 4 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 people. On the material side alone functions of this sort 
 provide us with what seem now to be essentials of city life. 
 The plotting, grading, and paving of streets and sidewalks, 
 and the construction of drainage systems are municipal duties 
 in the smallest cities. In most cities, too, the supply of water, 
 not only for public purposes, but for private consumption, is 
 clearly accepted as a municipal function. Other related 
 matters of municipal concern are the lighting and local 
 transportation systems ; and although most often the immedi- 
 ate management of these are intrusted to private corporations, 
 these corporations depend upon rights from the city; while 
 in Great Britain and Germany these undertakings are to a 
 large extent managed directly by the municipal authorities, 
 and in the United States there is a growing tendency toward 
 municipal ownership of public lighting plants. In this group 
 of activities we may place also the provisions of parks and 
 other recreation grounds for the people. 
 
 Still another group of municipal functions are those of a 
 charitable nature; and these have developed from the simple 
 relief of starving paupers to the maintenance of homes for the 
 aged and infirm, hospitals where the sick may be restored to 
 health and vigor, and other minor forms of philanthropic 
 effort. 
 
 In addition to these means of ministering to the material 
 and physical needs of the community, the modern munici- 
 pality does a vast and increasing work for the development 
 of the intellectual, aesthetic, and moral faculties of the citizens. 
 Even the elementary schools of to-day do much more than 
 teach their pupils how to read and write, to add and mul- 
 tiply; while these are supplemented by high schools and 
 public libraries; and in not a few places are to be found 
 municipal museums of art and science, municipal theatres 
 and opera houses, and even municipal universities. 
 
 Does this outline indicate too broad a realm of municipal 
 activity? If so, one can only emphasize that this has not 
 been a promise of the future, but what is now being attempted
 
 SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 5 
 
 and at least in part accomplished at the present time. The 
 various functions named are those now being exercised, not 
 only in the largest cities, but also in smaller places and in all 
 the progressive countries of the world. 
 
 Perhaps we may perceive faintly something of the signifi- 
 cance of this expansive field of action, by a fact or two about 
 the expenditure it involves. A hundred years ago the city 
 of New York with a population of 60,000 spent about $100,000 
 a year, or less than $2 per capita. To-day that city spends 
 for current maintenance and operation of the various munici- 
 pal institutions over $100,000,000 a year, or $25 per capita; 
 and a variable number of millions in addition for construction 
 of new municipal works. Smaller cities spend rather less 
 proportionately; but to show that this development is not 
 confined to the largest cities we may recall that in the city 
 of Ann Arbor (with a population of 15,000) the annual taxes 
 amount to $150,000 a year, or five times as much per capita 
 as they were in New York when that city had four times 
 the present population of Ann Arbor. 
 
 If these facts suggest anything of the importance of the 
 work of municipal government, there should be little need of 
 urging the interest and concern of every good citizen in that 
 work and the government which has it in charge. But there 
 are other considerations which show that it is necessary to 
 arouse the attention and energy of many people if the work 
 in this country is to be done efficiently and thoroughly. Mu- 
 nicipal government in America has been and is subject to con- 
 stant and severe criticism ; and it can be stated positively that 
 it is not only far below what is possible, but that in many respects 
 it is below the standards of accomplishment in other coun- 
 tries of the world, which do not have our advantages and are 
 usually considered inferior in most respects to our own. 
 
 Mr. Bryce, the well-known British critic of our institutions, 
 has said that our municipal government is a failure " the 
 one conspicuous failure," in fact. And many others have 
 accepted and reiterated his judgment. The statement,
 
 6 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 however, like most rhetorical generalizations, is too sweeping 
 and too indefinite; and it will be more exact to speak of the 
 failures or defects than to brand the whole by a term which 
 indicates a complete lack of success. 
 
 Of these defects in American municipal government, we 
 may note first the frequent disclosure of gross corruption of 
 and by municipal officials. From the time of the Tweed Ring 
 in New York to the latest revelations in San Francisco the 
 existence of corrupt officials has been made notoriously evi- 
 dent from time to time and from one city to another. And 
 it is such cases which give rise to the impression in some quar- 
 ters that a chronic state of flagrant corruption is the normal 
 condition in most American cities. But I venture to believe 
 that cases of gross corruption, such as those mentioned, are 
 on the whole exceptional; that they are sometimes exagger- 
 ated by the heated language of exciting political contests, 
 and the demands of the newspaper press and its readers for 
 sensational news ; and that when they occur, as they do 
 far too often, they are the out-croppings of more per- 
 manent and more general defects in our municipal govern- 
 ment. And it may be said that the undue emphasis laid 
 on notorious cases of gross corruption tends to delude the 
 people in the many cities where no such cases have arisen 
 into believing that their municipal government is as good as 
 it can be made. 
 
 But these more permanent and more general defects need 
 more special attention. They may be summed up under two 
 general heads : waste, and inadequate service. On the one 
 hand, the municipal work does not meet the needs of the 
 community. Things undertaken are poorly done, or under- 
 taken on too small a scale; and many things which ought 
 to be done are not attempted at all. The streets may be 
 kept in no better order perhaps not so good as a cross- 
 country road. The police force may be insufficient in number 
 and lack training and discipline. The water-supply may be 
 unsanitary. And the public library and other institutions
 
 SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 7 
 
 may be noticeable only by their absence. On the other hand, 
 the cost of the works undertaken is too often in excess of 
 the results accomplished or the results needed. At one time, 
 the waste may be due to extravagance in starting some 
 work on a larger scale than is necessary; at another time, to a 
 mistaken effort at economy in beginning a petty scheme, 
 when a larger one presently appears essential ; or still again, to 
 simple carelessness and ignorance in executing the details 
 of any project. 
 
 The proximate causes of these defects are to be found partly 
 in our municipal legislation, partly in the officials. Those 
 due to legislation shall be passed over briefly at this time, as 
 the legal problems involve much difficult technical discussion, 
 for which there is no room here, while the remedies lie largely 
 with the state legislatures. Their general nature may be 
 briefly noted as a lack of legal power conferred on the city, 
 the absence in most cases of any definite principles of munici- 
 pal organization, and the confusing practice of special and 
 detailed legislation. The causes due to municipal officials 
 may be reduced to two : ignorance, and moral deficiency. By 
 ignorance is not meant necessarily illiteracy, or even lack 
 of a good general education, but ignorance of the matters 
 which the officials are charged to perform. This is some- 
 times due to a lack of general ability, sometimes to lack of 
 knowledge and experience, the latter lack being continually 
 renewed by the custom of changing officials as soon as they 
 have learned the duties of their offices. Many of the elective 
 offices in most of our cities have no political functions to per- 
 form; and the most efficient administration can only be 
 secured by retaining experienced men in such positions as 
 long as possible. The term "moral deficiency " is broad enough 
 to cover the most flagrant case of bribery; but there is a 
 large number of municipal officials who would probably scorn 
 a direct bribe and yet fail to see that they are guilty of much 
 the same kind of delinquency whenever they appoint any one 
 to a position in the public service without reference to his
 
 8 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 competence and because of personal or party affiliations. 
 Where incompetence and lack of moral stamina are combined 
 in one official, the results are likely to be so intolerable as 
 to rouse public opinion and secure at least a temporary im- 
 provement at the succeeding election. But it often happens 
 that the scheming and sordid politician has the practical 
 knowledge and experience of municipal problems which the 
 man of undoubted integrity lacks. The former must become 
 imbued with higher principles, the latter must add to his 
 character knowledge and experience in municipal affairs, 
 before either can make a satisfactory official. 
 
 But our analysis must go behind the delinquencies of the 
 officials to the reasons which explain why such persons are 
 chosen to office ; and here we shall find the principal ultimate 
 causes of the defects in our municipal government. 
 
 Among the important factors which result in the selection 
 of municipal officials who are either incompetent or dishonest, 
 or otherwise deficient in their standards of public duty, we 
 may note first the influence of political parties and their 
 organized machinery. This influence is aggravated in many 
 places by the characters of the men who have gained control 
 of the local party organizations; and this aggravation may 
 be reduced by legislation regulating party primaries and 
 nominations. But even if this reform were effectively accom- 
 plished, so long as voting at municipal elections is based on 
 national party affiliations it will be impossible to secure the 
 best municipal officials and the best municipal government. 
 In many European cities the political organizations for 
 municipal elections have no connection with the national 
 party organizations; and in several American cities there 
 have been formed similar independent local organizations, 
 which in some cases notably in Cambridge, Mass. have 
 kept the national parties out of the field of municipal elections. 
 Even where this plan is not adopted, it is still possible for 
 the individual voter to exercise freely his right of independent 
 voting between the various candidates of the different parties.
 
 SOME PHASES OF MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 9 
 
 This latter plan has been followed effectively in Chicago, 
 where a special organization known as the Municipal Voters' 
 League devotes itself, not to making nominations, but to 
 making non-partisan investigations of the various candidates 
 of all parties, and publishing their information for the benefit 
 of the voters. 
 
 But either of these plans for offsetting the defects of par- 
 tisan-voting at municipal elections requires for its success an 
 intelligent, public-spirited interest on the part of the citizens. 
 And it is the lack of this intelligent interest which is probably 
 the most important factor in the choice of improper officials. 
 This criticism of the voters is precisely similar to that pre- 
 viously made in reference to the officials. There is, first, an 
 intellectual deficiency ignorance; and secondly, moral 
 deficiencies. In our large cities the ignorance is to a large 
 extent the ignorance of the illiterate; but both there and in 
 smaller cities there is too often a less excusable ignorance on 
 the part of the best educated classes in the community as to 
 the organization and functions of the municipal government 
 and the character and competence of the candidates for mu- 
 nicipal office. So too, the moral deficiencies are, on the one 
 hand, those of the poorer classes, varying from the acceptance 
 of a direct bribe to voting out of gratitude for personal favors ; 
 and, on the other hand, those of the well-to-do and educated 
 classes from bribe-giving to a selfish indifference to the 
 interests of the community. 
 
 So long as these conditions continue among the inhabitants 
 of our cities, no improvement in laws and the machinery of 
 government will suffice to secure permanently satisfactory 
 municipal administration. What is needed above all is the 
 education of the citizens both mentally and morally, by 
 instruction in the nature and functions of municipal govern- 
 ment and the qualifications of candidates for office, and by 
 the inculcation of higher standards in the exercise of their 
 duties as citizens. Perhaps, more than anything else, it is 
 essential to overcome the indifference of those engrossed in
 
 10 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 business, professional, and social life, to make them realize 
 their concern in the public life of the community, to induce 
 them to inform themselves on the municipal affairs of their 
 locality and to become active workers for the improvement 
 of local conditions. Sometimes the attempt is made to 
 arouse this public interest simply as an unpleasant duty, 
 which calls for a sacrifice of individual interests for the sake 
 of others. It is vastly better and nearer the truth to empha- 
 size the interrelation between the interests of the individuals 
 and the interests of the community. There is need for the 
 development of a larger social consciousness, for the realiza- 
 tion of the mutual interdependence of all the citizens of a 
 community and the importance of the common life, for a 
 fuller appreciation of the thought that "none of us liveth 
 to himself." This is the new philosophy of society. It is 
 also an old philosophy that has never been better expressed 
 than in the fable which the old Roman Menenius Agrippa 
 told the seceding Plebeians nearly 2500 years ago : " Once 
 upon a time the members of the body refused to work any 
 longer for the stomach, which led a lazy life and enjoyed all 
 the benefit of their labors. But receiving no longer any 
 nourishment from the stomach, they soon began to pine away, 
 and found that it was to the stomach they owed their life 
 and strength."
 
 II 
 
 MUCH has been written during recent years about the defects 
 of American municipal government. And all sorts of reme- 
 dies have been proposed, and many of them put to the test 
 of experience. Discussion and agitation, followed by legisla- 
 tion and the election of better officials, have wrought great 
 improvement in many communities ; and even the most recent 
 disclosures of intolerable conditions have been signs of an 
 awakened public opinion and the direct cause of uprooting 
 some evils. But no one has suggested that we have as yet 
 reached a state of perfection in municipal government, or 
 that we are in any immediate danger of attaining such a state. 
 
 It is not the purpose of this paper to discuss all of the prob- 
 lems that have arisen in connection with our municipal affairs, 
 nor to propose remedies for all of the difficulties and evils 
 that still exist. No attention will be given to such questions 
 as the scope of municipal functions or the political substructure 
 underlying the organization of government. The task here 
 undertaken is to consider only those features of the complex 
 municipal situation on which a student of public administra- 
 tion may be supposed to be able to throw some light. 
 
 These features may be considered under two main heads: 
 (1) the problems connected with the local machinery of 
 municipal organization and the interrelations of local officials ; 
 and (2) the problems connected with the relations of the city 
 to the government of the state. Under each division, the 
 existing arrangements will be briefly summarized, their defects 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Annals of the American Academy of Social and 
 Political Science, XXVII, 132 (January, 1906). 
 
 11
 
 12 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 will be pointed out and the various remedies hitherto applied, 
 and plans will be suggested for future action. It will be ad- 
 mitted frankly that no scheme of purely administrative 
 reform will offer a complete solution of all the municipal 
 problems; but it is a false logic which deduces from this the 
 belief that administrative reform is of no importance; and 
 this paper is written in the conviction that some of the funda- 
 mental difficulties are administrative in character, and that 
 administrative reforms are among the essential conditions 
 of successful municipal government in this country. The 
 basis for the discussion of administrative reforms will be found 
 in a municipal program, adopted by the National Municipal 
 League; but amendments to this plan as seem desirable will 
 also be suggested. 
 
 LOCAL ORGANIZATION 
 
 One of the first facts that becomes obvious to any student 
 of municipal government in the United States is the confused 
 and complicated variety of local administrative arrange- 
 ments, and the lack of consistent principles of municipal 
 organization, not only in the cities as a whole, but even in 
 most of the cities taken individually. Starting with a simple 
 system of council government, this was first altered about 
 1820 by a limited application of the theory of the separation 
 of legislative and executive powers in the popular election of 
 mayors; while subsequently (since 1850) the division of 
 municipal powers in the hands of separate and largely inde- 
 pendent authorities has been developed to a remarkable 
 degree, without any guiding principle and in a way that 
 defies generalization or classification. In more recent years, 
 some of our cities have secured a system of municipal organi- 
 zation based in part at least on some fundamental ideas. 
 These have been for the most part a stricter application of 
 the theory of separation of the legislative and executive 
 powers, with the concentration of the latter in the hands of 
 the chief executive, as in the national administration; but
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 13 
 
 in a few cases the centralization of authority in the hands of 
 the mayor has tended toward the abandonment of the theory 
 of separation. 
 
 There are two factors in American municipal organization 
 which are practically universal, and may therefore be taken 
 as the necessary bases for any systematic scheme. These are 
 a council and a mayor, both elected directly by popular vote. 
 Washington, D.C., is the only city which has been an excep- 
 tion to this rule for any considerable length of time. 1 
 
 THE COUNCIL 
 
 When we turn to examine the structure and powers of 
 these two common factors, we find ourselves at once in the 
 midst of diversity and often of confusion. The typical form 
 of the council is that of a single body elected by wards or 
 districts for a one or two year term. Many of the large cities 
 six out of the twelve with over 300,000 population 
 have a bicameral council. In many of these the smaller 
 branch of the council is elected from the whole city instead 
 of by districts; the cities in Ohio, Indiana, and Iowa, and 
 some others have a small number of councilmen elected at 
 large, in addition to the ward representatives; and in San 
 Francisco and a few other cities the whole membership of 
 the council is chosen at large. In most American cities 
 council members now receive some compensation; but the 
 older rule of gratuitous service still prevails in New England, 
 Pennsylvania, and is frequently found in Southern cities 
 and occasionally in other parts of the country. 
 
 1 Within recent years a new plan of municipal organization has been 
 established in Galveston and Houston, Texas; and by legislation of 1907 
 similar methods have been authorized in Kansas and Iowa. These 
 place all the powers of municipal government in the hands of a small 
 elective board or commission, which acts collectively as a council, while 
 the several members are the heads of various city departments. This 
 experiment seems to promise a more effective administrative system; 
 but it does not provide for any adequate grant of important legislative 
 powers to local authorities.
 
 14 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Almost every one of these elements of council organization 
 has been the subject of criticism. It is pointed out that 
 a single council elected by wards, even if successful in repre- 
 senting the local interests of the various districts, makes no 
 adequate provision for the general interest of the whole city. 
 In addition the district system offers other difficulties in 
 cities, and especially in large cities. The ward limits are 
 artificial and seldom represent any natural social grouping 
 of the population. Frequent changes of boundaries and 
 the constant changes of residence on the part of the people 
 hinder the development of a common social life within the 
 political district. While even in the face of readjustments 
 of boundaries, population movements go on so rapidly that 
 there is seldom even the crudest approximation to repre- 
 sentation in proportion to population; and in the largest 
 cities at least the districts over-represented are those in the 
 control of the worst elements in the population. 
 
 A bicameral council with one house elected at large might 
 seem to meet some of these objections ; but in fact, as generally 
 established, it simply adds another body chosen in a way 
 which prevents the representation of different interests, 
 and thus weakens the deliberative character of the council. 
 In practical experience, too, it has not been found that the 
 bicameral system is in any way necessary, or that it secures 
 any improvement in the management of municipal affairs. 
 
 In reference to salaries, it is urged on the one hand that no 
 payment induces aldermen to accept or to demand com- 
 pensation for their services in an irregular way, which often 
 becomes either a system of bribery or blackmail; and on 
 the other hand it is said that any salary makes the post 
 one for which impecunious politicians will enter into active 
 competition. 
 
 The plan of the National Municipal League recommends 
 the election of a single chambered city council on a general 
 ticket, although providing for the possible retention of the 
 district system in cities of over 25,000. Does not this go
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 15 
 
 too far in ignoring the idea of local representation? It may 
 be admitted that the present ward system is usually un- 
 satisfactory; but are there not in every city sectional divi- 
 sions with tolerably distinct municipal interests and some 
 elements of common social life? Such divisions ought to be 
 recognized and emphasized in the political system. They 
 should have fairly permanent boundaries; and the district 
 for electing council members should be also a district for 
 other municipal purposes, such as schools, police, fire brigade, 
 and the like, and indeed still further for larger political 
 interests, such as the election of members of the state legis- 
 lature. By thus concentrating the political interests of the 
 same people in a common district, the germ of social unity 
 and local spirit could be highly developed. Such districts 
 would ordinarily be larger than city wards at the present 
 time, and the internal transfers of population within the 
 city would be more largely within the district, and would 
 thus more often be made without requiring any readjust- 
 ment of political relations. Moreover, as each district 
 would have several members in the council, the exact number 
 could be adjusted at frequent intervals in proportion to the 
 changes in population, without chahging district boundaries. 
 Besides such a district system, the plan now in use in 
 several states of the Middle West, of electing a small number 
 of members of the council at large also seems desirable. Such 
 members would probably be more widely known throughout 
 the city, and likely on this account to be men of large ability 
 and character, and also likely to secure better consideration 
 for the questions where local interests should give way to 
 more general views. It may further be noted that these 
 arrangements are adapted to various forms of minority and 
 proportional representation; but even without this feature 
 the district members will undoubtedly include representatives 
 of different shades of political opinion on various questions 
 of public policy, and the council will thus continue to be 
 a body adapted to deliberation and discussion.
 
 16 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 A system of council organization somewhat similar to 
 that outlined was in operation in New York City from 1873 
 to 1882. And it is perhaps worthy of note that during this 
 decade there was less criticism of municipal government in 
 the metropolis than in any other period of equal length for 
 the last fifty years, and that the abandonment of the system 
 was due, not to any public dissatisfaction, but apparently 
 for the sole purpose of strengthening the system of party 
 machinery and increasing partisan influences in the municipal 
 government. 
 
 An examination of the powers of municipal councils in- 
 volves two distinct or at least distinguishable topics : 
 the subject-matter of council activity, and the methods of 
 council action. In both fields the diversity of detail and 
 the difficulty of generalization is enormous. It may, how- 
 ever, be said, under the first head, that municipal councils 
 generally have some power in reference to the protection 
 of persons and property and the construction and manage- 
 ment of local works of public improvement, and often they 
 have some control over public charity; but seldom do they 
 have much direct voice in reference to public education. 
 In any case the authority of the council is strictly limited to 
 the specific grants made by the state legislature. These 
 legislative grants are not given in general terms, but are 
 minutely enumerated, and the courts have uniformly applied 
 the doctrine of strict construction to all such grants. In 
 consequence, while in the smaller cities the councils have 
 ordinarily about as much authority as they wish to exercise, 
 in the larger cities where the need and demand for municipal 
 action is much greater, the councils are constantly appealing 
 to the legislature for larger powers. 
 
 Methods of council action may be considered as legislative 
 or .administrative. In their constitution, municipal councils 
 are organized on similar principles to our legislatures; and 
 this idea has been retained in the plan proposed in this paper. 
 And in a vague sense the councils have been considered as
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 17 
 
 the body in the municipal government corresponding to the 
 legislatures in the state and national governments. But it 
 must be said that the law-makers have never thoroughly 
 recognized this. Indeed, the judicial doctrine laid down 
 as a general rule, that all legislative power not granted to 
 Congress is vested in the state legislatures and may not be 
 delegated, is in direct contradiction to the idea that the 
 councils are legislative bodies. Nevertheless, some state 
 constitutions have expressly provided that local legislative 
 power may be delegated to local bodies; while the body 
 of statutory legislation on municipal government does in 
 fact give a limited amount of legislative power to municipal 
 councils. 
 
 Legislative power as exercised by Congress and the state 
 legislatures seems to consist of three main elements: the 
 power to enact laws applying to the community at large; 
 the power to organize a system of officials and regulate their 
 functions; and the power to levy taxes and appropriate 
 money to maintain the administrative system thus organized. 
 Municipal councils have the first of these, to a limited degree, 
 in their power to enact local ordinances and by-laws on 
 specified subjects. But such ordinance power is sometimes 
 given to administrative authorities such as boards of health, 
 police commissioners, and park boards. They have the 
 third class of powers also to a more or less limited extent. 
 But they have in most cases only a most restricted authority 
 in reference to powers of the second class. 
 
 As to the power over administrative organization, munici- 
 pal charters usually provide so completely for all the officials 
 of any importance that the municipal councils find little 
 scope for further action except in the creation of minor 
 positions such as milk inspectors or sealers of weights and 
 measures; and in many of the larger cities this power of 
 establishing minor offices is vested not in the council, but in 
 an authority supposed to be administrative, while in the 
 new Ohio code such power has been given to the boards of
 
 18 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 public service in every city in that state. In this respect 
 city charters have carried to an absurd extreme a feature 
 of our state constitutions where these have departed from 
 the altogether excellent rule followed in the national 
 constitution. 
 
 One state stands out as a notable exception to this rule. 
 The municipal corporation act of Illinois, after providing 
 for a comparatively small number of officials in every city, 
 authorizes the municipal council by a two-thirds vote to 
 establish such other offices as it deems necessary, and to 
 discontinue any of these offices by a like vote at the end of 
 a fiscal year. Thus in the city of Chicago such important 
 offices as those of comptroller and commissioner of public 
 works have been established by council ordinance. 
 
 In the exercise of such legislative powers as they have, 
 municipal councils are generally restricted by the veto power 
 of the mayor, in the same way as Congress and most of the 
 state legislatures are restricted by the veto power of the 
 President and governors. 
 
 In most of the smaller cities, and in New England and 
 Pennsylvania even in cities of considerable size, municipal 
 councils still retain and exercise many administrative powers. 
 To some extent these powers are exercised by the council as 
 a whole, by the issuance of specific orders to agents and 
 employees, and by the appointment of officials and their 
 subordinates. In other respects, such powers are exercised 
 immediately by council committees, who have direct super- 
 vision over the municipal employees. Even in many larger 
 cities where these powers are no longer in the hands of the 
 councils, appointments to office are effective only after being 
 confirmed by them, this control over appointments being 
 sometimes used to secure some patronage for the individual 
 members. In Chicago and many of the large cities, as well 
 as the smaller ones, the council through its Finance Com- 
 mittee is the controlling factor in initiating proposals for 
 expenditure as well as in passing the appropriations; but in
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 19 
 
 the larger cities of New York State and some other cities 
 the budget is prepared by a small administrative board, 
 and the council is not permitted to appropriate more than 
 the sums provided in the budget. 
 
 Under the program of the National Municipal League, 
 the legislative powers of city councils would be vastly in- 
 creased. The ordinance power is to include general authority 
 in reference to the "good government, order and security 
 of the city and its inhabitants." Broad grants of power 
 to deal with public works, institutions and certain com- 
 mercial undertakings are given ; and these are made effective 
 by a comprehensive grant of taxing power. The council is 
 made the general legislative authority in all matters, subject, 
 however, to the veto power of the mayor; and with detailed 
 restrictions in reference to granting away rights and fran- 
 chises in the public streets. The council, too, is to have 
 almost complete power in organizing the administrative 
 departments. On the other hand, the council cannot ap- 
 point to any office, except that of comptroller; and it seems 
 to be intended that the council shall have no powers of direct 
 administration. 
 
 Several recent municipal charters have provisions along 
 the line of those recommendations. The general law for the 
 four cities of the second class in New York State vests the 
 legislative power and only the legislative power in the city 
 councils. A more emphatic statement is placed in the new 
 charter of Portland, Ore.; and another in the latest (1900) 
 charter of the city of New York. But it would seem that 
 these clauses refer only to the ordinance power; and the 
 equally important power of organizing administrative offices 
 has apparently been effectively granted only in the law of 
 Illinois previously mentioned. 1 
 
 1 In Michigan where the state constitution specifically authorizes 
 the legislature to confer local legislative power on city councils, the 
 Supreme Court has held that this applies only to the power of passing 
 general ordinances, and that the legislature may not delegate to city 
 councils the power of organizing administrative departments.
 
 20 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 It is not entirely clear that all municipal councils should 
 be restrained from exercising any administrative functions. 
 In small cities, where the amount of municipal work is limited, 
 there is no absolute necessity for separating legislative and 
 administrative functions, and council committees may well 
 discharge the latter duties and save the expense of additional 
 officials. In large cities the distinction is much more im- 
 portant; the increased volume of business makes a greater 
 demand on the time of aldermen than can safely be ex- 
 pected from the kind of men who ought to be members of 
 the councils; and better administrative management can 
 be secured by specializing that work in the hands of experts 
 in the different fields who can be paid to give their whole 
 time to the municipal service. 
 
 "With a careful separation of powers, the legislative func- 
 tion can be intrusted to typical everyday Americans from 
 middle life who yet have broad enough training to enable 
 them to see the interests of the city as a whole. In most 
 cities strictly legislative duties would not seriously interfere 
 with a man's regular business, and therefore the council- 
 men need not either be rich or receive high salaries from 
 the city." l 
 
 THE MAYOR 
 
 The mayor has the longest pedigree of any of our American 
 public officers. As far back as the sixth century we hear of 
 the mayors of the palace in the Frankish kingdoms, the last 
 of whom, Karl Martel, was grandfather to the Emperor 
 Charlemagne. A few centuries later the name appears again 
 both in France and England as the chief officer of a city, and 
 in that capacity it has come down to our own time. Ameri- 
 can mayors occupy an intermediate position between the 
 purely honorary and social dignity of the English office and 
 the professional public administrator of Germany, with a 
 tendency in recent years to confer on the officer legal powers 
 
 1 Wilcox, The American City, p. 306.
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 21 
 
 in some respects analogous to those of a mayor in France. 
 In this country the office is filled by direct popular vote, for 
 terms varying from one to four years. The one year term 
 is too short ; it should be at least two. In most cities of over 
 25,000 population, and in many smaller cities, the incum- 
 bent receives a salary, in cities with over 100,000 popu- 
 lation, usually from $2000 to $5000 a year, and in five cities 
 from $10,000 to $15,000. 1 
 
 Although generally considered as primarily an executive 
 officer, the mayor has always had important duties in relation 
 to the council and legislative matters. In small cities, he 
 is in most cases the presiding officer of the council; and has 
 this position even in such important cities as Chicago, Provi- 
 dence, and Grand Rapids. In the last named he also ap- 
 points the committees of the council. But in most of the 
 larger cities this connection of the mayor with the council 
 has ceased. On the other hand, in all the larger cities and 
 many small cities, he has a limited veto over the acts of the 
 council, which in many cases includes the power to disap- 
 prove items in appropriation bills, sometimes includes the 
 power to disapprove separate provisions of any ordinance, 
 and in a few cities is made more effective than the veto power 
 of the President and state governors by requiring a larger 
 vote than the traditional two-thirds to override his disap- 
 proval. In the cities of New York State, the mayors have 
 an additional legislative power to disapprove special acts of 
 the state legislature applying to their cities, this disapproval 
 operating as a veto unless the legislature repasses the bill. 
 
 In respect to administrative powers, the principles of 
 executive authority employed in the national government 
 have been but slowly and gradually applied to city mayors. 
 In many small cities, and in some of considerable size (the 
 latter mostly in New England and Ohio) the mayor has even 
 yet little or no appointing power and no effective means of 
 
 1 Racine, Wis., seems to be the largest city where no salary ia 
 paid.
 
 22 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 controlling the other officials; and has thus still less relative 
 authority than most of the state governors. In other cities, 
 including most of the larger places, he now generally has 
 powers analogous to those of a state governor: the right to 
 nominate to the council for the principal positions not filled 
 by popular election, and some power of removing officials 
 for cause. In Illinois cities, the scope of this limited power 
 over appointments may be greatly enlarged as the council 
 creates new offices; and in the same state the mayor has 
 also a large power of removal which gives him effective 
 means of control over the other officials and strengthens 
 his influence in appointments. In Chicago the mayor's 
 power of nomination extends to most of the important 
 positions, and in practice has been equivalent to the absolute 
 power of appointment. In Cleveland for twelve years 
 (1891-1903) the mayor had a very extended power of nomina- 
 tion, which in practice operated to give him complete control 
 over most of the important positions. 
 
 During the last ten years, in a number of important cities, 
 the mayor's power of appointment and removal has been 
 still further increased. The mayors of the six largest cities 
 in New York State, of Boston, of all cities in Indiana, and 
 of a few other cities have now the sole and absolute power 
 of appointing the heads of most of the municipal departments ; 
 and in the same cities, with the addition of the four largest 
 cities in Pennsylvania, mayors have the power of removing 
 at any time the appointed heads of departments. Under 
 this system the executive authority and responsibility is 
 concentrated in the mayor, except for a few officials still 
 elected by popular vote. 
 
 In the program of the National Municipal League, this 
 latest development of the mayor's authority is adopted, and 
 indeed strengthened by making the mayor the only elective 
 executive officer, and extending his power of appointment 
 and removal to all administrative officers except the comp- 
 troller. At the same time the mayor's limited veto power
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 23 
 
 over council ordinances is retained ; and he is also to prepare 
 and submit the annual budget. 
 
 This concentration of executive authority in the hands of 
 the mayor has been criticised, as enabling that official to use 
 his power to build up a "political machine." This was 
 the main argument of those who planned the recent Ohio 
 municipal code, which relegates the mayor to a position of 
 "innocuous desuetude," yet the system there established 
 was that which has enabled one of the most notorious "ma- 
 chines" in the country to be maintained in the city of Cin- 
 cinnati Every system of appointment or election can be 
 abused in this way, so long as positions in the municipal 
 service are given as rewards for campaign work. The com- 
 plete plan of the National Municipal League will restrict 
 the possibility of this abuse to small limits by the merit system 
 in filling all subordinate positions; and it is felt that the 
 importance of the principal offices, and the responsibility 
 of the mayor's power will in most cases secure the appoint- 
 ment of competent heads of departments. 
 
 One writer in a recent article advocates a still further 
 development of executive authority. 1 He holds that the 
 organic defect in municipal organization "lies in the fact 
 that the executive and legislative departments, in addition 
 to being separately constituted, are also disconnected, and 
 this very disconnection has prevented in practice the degree 
 of separation in their functions which their integrity requires." 
 His remedy is to give the executive complete legislative 
 initiative, with the right to demand a vote on proposed 
 measures. 
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE DEPARTMENTS 
 
 Our discussion of the officials who deal with particular 
 branches of municipal administration must be very brief. 
 Any description of existing arrangements is out of the ques- 
 
 1 H. J. Ford, in Annals of American Academy of Political and Social 
 Science, March, 1904.
 
 24 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 tion, for the situation may well be described as chaotic: 
 a chaos in regard to the forms of organization, the terms of 
 service, the methods of election or appointment, and the 
 relations of the various officials to the council, to the mayor, 
 and to each other. A large element of variety in some of 
 these respects is almost inevitable: the number of officials 
 and separate departments must vary with the size of the 
 city and the scope of municipal functions; and the extent 
 to which unsalaried service can be advantageously secured 
 can hardly be fixed by a hard and fast rule. But the existing 
 confusion goes far beyond what is either nesessary or ex- 
 cusable, and is the cause of constant friction and dissatis- 
 faction in municipal operations. 
 
 Something may be said about conditions in those cities 
 where a more orderly system has been introduced. Most 
 of the cities where the mayor's power has been increased, 
 place single salaried commissioners at the head of the various 
 departments, and some other large cities, e.g., Detroit, have 
 also partially introduced this same feature But in every 
 case some branches of administration remain under the 
 supervision of boards, and there is no fixed rule as to which 
 departments are under boards and which under single com- 
 missioners. 
 
 In most cities the various municipal bureaus form a hetero- 
 geneous list, frequently numbering from twenty to thirty or 
 more, with no official connection even between those whose 
 duties are most closely related. But a number of cities 
 have made progress in grouping related offices into impor- 
 tant departments. Thus in St. Louis the heads of the various 
 public works bureaus, including the parks, streets, sewers, 
 and water bureaus, are brought together in the board of 
 public improvements; and in the larger cities of New York 
 and Pennsylvania the public works department has been 
 made to include most of the bureaus of this kind. In Ohio 
 cities, under the new code, the department of public service 
 embraces not only the management of all the municipal
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 25 
 
 engineering works, but also the charitable and correctional 
 institutions, going too far in combining unrelated offices. 
 Another development has been in establishing departments 
 of public safety, bringing together the police and fire brigades 
 and usually also the offices for sanitary and building inspec- 
 tion. This department is now to be found in some of the 
 larger cities of New York, Pennsylvania, and Indiana, in all 
 the Ohio cities, and occasionally in other places. 
 
 Most advance in this direction is to be found in the four 
 cities of the second class in New York State. Here practically 
 all the municipal service is organized in seven main depart- 
 ments. This plan seems to have been taken, with some 
 modifications, from the so-called "federal plan" of Cleveland 
 (1891-1903); and another feature of that plan is authorized 
 in the New York cities; viz, the periodic meetings of the 
 heads of departments with the mayor, as a cabinet for the 
 discussion of questions of common interest to secure agree- 
 ment on harmonious lines. In Cleveland the "cabinet" 
 was constituted as a board of control with important legal 
 powers ; but in the New York cities it has been left to develop 
 its own place in the municipal system. 
 
 In the new municipal code of Indiana (1905) from five to 
 eight departments are established in cities of over 10,000 
 population, and provision is made for monthly meetings of 
 the mayor and the heads of departments. This "cabinet" 
 is authorized to adopt rules and regulations for the administra- 
 tion of the departments, including rules governing admission 
 to the subordinate municipal service. 
 
 The plan of the National Municipal League does not provide 
 in detail for the administrative departments; but leaves 
 these to be organized by the council or by the special locally 
 framed charters according to the needs of the city. But 
 there is certainly need in most cities for more careful attention 
 to this problem of departmental organization ; and the larger 
 cities of the country will find the plans that have been men- 
 tioned well worth their attention.
 
 26 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Subordinate positions in the municipal service in most 
 cities are filled and held at the pleasure of the changing heads 
 of departments and bureaus. And one of the most serious 
 abuses in municipal administration has been the frequent 
 changes in such positions for partisan and political purposes. 
 In the cities of Massachusetts and New York, and in Phila- 
 delphia, Chicago, and New Orleans the system of open com- 
 petitive examinations has been established. And in some 
 other cities the police and fire departments are recruited 
 under a merit system. There can be no question that the 
 principles of civil service reform should be thoroughly applied 
 to the whole municipal service. 1 
 
 THE CITY AND THE STATE 
 
 Of equal importance with the problems of local organization 
 are the problems of the relations between the city and the 
 state. For in the United States, as in all other countries, 
 cities are not independent political communities, but districts 
 in a larger political area and subordinate in various ways to 
 the higher governmental authorities. In the United States 
 this subordination is to the government of the states. There 
 are many evidences that the prevailing relations between 
 the city and state authorities are unsatisfactory, and the 
 remedy most widely suggested is a demand, usually vague 
 and inarticulate, for municipal "home rule." Some atten- 
 tion may therefore be given to explaining the present arrange- 
 ments and to presenting a definite plan for a better system. 
 
 At the outset it may be noted that in our fundamental 
 political document, the national constitution, cities are in 
 no way recognized as having any existence; and that under 
 the principle of residual powers, cities are created by the 
 states, which have complete power of control over them, 
 and may even destroy their political existence. 2 But the 
 powers of the states are for the most part exercised by the 
 
 1 Cf. Essay III. 
 
 2 U. S. v. B. & O. R. R. Co., 17 Wall. 322 (1872).
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 27 
 
 state governments; and these are established and limited 
 by the state constitutions. The more practical question is 
 therefore as to the relations of the cities to the state legislatures, 
 the state executive and administrative authorities, and the 
 judiciary. 
 
 LEGISLATIVE CONTROL 
 
 In the absence of specific limitations in the state con- 
 stitutions, the power of the legislature in most states is held 
 by the courts to be practically coextensive with the power 
 of the states. A municipal corporation has only such powers 
 as are expressly enumerated or clearly implied in its charter 
 or the general laws; and the legislature "may, where there 
 is no constitutional inhibition, erect, change, divide, and 
 even abolish them at pleasure, as it deems the public good to 
 require." l 
 
 In Michigan, however, and to a less extent in Indiana 
 this doctrine has been somewhat modified; and the courts 
 have held that the legislature may not vest distinctively local 
 powers, such as management of public works, in state officers, 
 and may not compel a city to undertake local improvements 
 without its consent. More generally, too, it has been held 
 that the constitutional guarantees for the protection of pri- 
 vate property prevent the legislature from confiscating the 
 private property of a city. But with these exceptions, 
 restrictions on the power of the legislature must be based on 
 specific constitutional provisions. 
 
 State legislatures, in the exercise of this power over cities, 
 have generally granted the authority to elect local officials; 
 but have regulated in minute details the organization of the 
 municipal government and the powers and functions of 
 the municipal officials. In earlier days, and even at the 
 present time for most small cities, statutes on municipal 
 government have usually been enacted only on local initiative 
 and generally at the request of local members of the legis- 
 
 1 Dillon, Municipal Corporations, I, 93.
 
 28 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 lature without consideration by the whole legislature or 
 any public notice. As a result, there has accumulated a great 
 mass of special legislation in most of the states, overloading 
 the statutes with heterogeneous and conflicting provisions, 
 which make almost impossible an intelligent understanding 
 of municipal government and dissipate and confuse responsi- 
 bility for local affairs. 
 
 In most of the states containing large cities, legislation 
 for their government has been affected by other considera- 
 tions. Charters and charter amendments are passed not 
 only without public and local discussion, but also, in many 
 cases, against the wishes of the local officials and local mem- 
 bers of the legislature. Sometimes such legislation has had, 
 ostensibly at least, the immediate object of remedying some 
 municipal delinquency; but in many cases the most effective 
 motive has been to secure some partisan advantage for those 
 in control of the state government, when the city officers 
 belong to another political organization; while in some in- 
 stances such legislation has been enacted through the worst 
 sort of political jobbery, to confer privileges which could 
 not be secured from the local authorities. By such means 
 acts have been passed substituting state appointed officials 
 for local officers, compelling cities to carry out expensive 
 and unnecessary undertakings, and granting franchises in 
 the public streets with little or no compensation to the city. 
 The legislatures of New York, Pennsylvania, Ohio, and 
 Missouri have been most active in these methods of inter- 
 ference; but instances are not lacking in Massachusetts, 
 Illinois, Michigan, and other states. 
 
 It is over fifty years since the attempt was begun to remedy 
 the evils of special municipal legislation by constitutional 
 provisions prohibiting such legislation. The second con- 
 stitution of Ohio, adopted in 1851, contained several clauses 
 intended to abolish special legislation on municipal govern- 
 ment; other states followed this example, at first slowly, 
 but more rapidly since 1870; and at the present time about
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 29 
 
 half of the states forbid the legislature to enact special muni- 
 cipal legislation. These provisions have, however, had only 
 a partial success. The method of detailed legislation enumer- 
 ating municipal officers and powers was so firmly established, 
 that when it proved difficult to pass laws of that nature apply- 
 ing to cities of all sizes, the lawmakers, instead of changing 
 their method of legislation, devised methods of evading the 
 constitutional provisions. The most successful method was 
 the device of classifying cities; as the courts accepted a 
 statute applying to a class of cities as a general law, even 
 if there were only a single city in a class. The smaller cities 
 were then grouped into one class, and a general law applied 
 to them; but each of the larger cities was usually placed in 
 a class by itself; and the regime of special legislation with 
 its evils of confusion, partisanship, and corruption continued, 
 and indeed became worse than ever with the development 
 of cities in size and population. 
 
 In Illinois an effective general municipal law was enacted 
 hi 1872, which by granting large powers to all cities has been 
 successful in limiting special legislation in that state. But 
 even there some special legislation has been enacted, mainly 
 because the financial powers granted in the general law are 
 not adequate to the needs of the city of Chicago. In Ohio, 
 too, after fifty years of classified legislation, the Supreme 
 Court of the state felt compelled in 1902 to reverse its previous 
 rulings and to declare that statutes for a class of cities which 
 in fact applied only to a single city were contrary to the state 
 constitution. The result was the enactment of a new muni- 
 cipal code applying to all the cities of that state, which, 
 however, still goes so much into detail that it burdens the 
 smaller cities with a too cumbersome machinery. The new 
 municipal code of Indiana reduces the number of classes of 
 cities in that state to five. And Virginia has a general muni- 
 cipal law, supplemented, however, by some special legislation. 
 In some other states the smaller cities are organized under 
 a general law.
 
 30 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 New York State in 1894 adopted another method, in the 
 attempt to reduce the evils of legislative interference in 
 municipal affairs. The revised constitution of that year 
 itself establishes three classes of cities, and provides that any 
 bill applying to less than all the cities in one of these classes 
 must be submitted to the city concerned, and if disapproved 
 by the mayor or the mayor and council must be repassed by 
 the legislature and signed by the governor before it can be- 
 come a law. These provisions have secured a greater amount 
 of publicity to special legislation and have prevented the 
 enactment of some bills rushed through the legislature with- 
 out careful consideration. In the case of bills passed toward 
 the end of the session, the mayor's disapproval is also effective 
 until the next session of the legislature. But in many cases 
 the mayor's disapproval has served only to delay the enact- 
 ment; and partisan or corrupt influences have secured the 
 passage of measures over the local disapproval. 
 
 At the session of the Michigan legislature in 1903 a method 
 of procedure was adopted in reference to bills affecting the 
 city of Detroit, which secured the same advantage of publicity. 
 At the request of the Common Council of Detroit, no Detroit 
 bill was placed on its third reading, until after a public hear- 
 ing on the measure in the city. Such hearings were held 
 regularly on Saturday mornings during the session, being 
 attended by the local members of the legislature, a com- 
 mittee of the council, the newspaper reporters, and any one 
 interested in particular bills. This procedure could be 
 established in every state, and it ought not to be a difficult 
 matter to secure it. During the year it was in operation in 
 Michigan, it prevented the enactment of all measures to 
 which there was strong local opposition. It has proved, 
 however, inadequate as a means of securing needed legislation, 
 6wing to the difficulty of harmonizing the different factors. 
 
 Another method which prevents some of the abuses of 
 legislative interference is found in the constitutions of New 
 York and Kentucky, which provide that all local officers
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 31 
 
 must be locally elected. Even this, however, has been evaded 
 by creating special districts with appointive officers for the 
 conduct of functions usually municipal, or by transferring 
 such functions and officers from the city to the county. 
 
 Still another method found in several of the states west of 
 the Mississippi River, is that of allowing cities to frame their 
 own charters through a local convention analogous to a state 
 constitutional convention. A constitutional provision author- 
 izing this was first adopted in Missouri in 1875 for cities of 
 over 100,000 population, and this was early applied in the 
 city of St. Louis and later in Kansas City. In 1879 California 
 adopted a similar constitutional provision to that of Missouri, 
 which now applies to any city of over 3500 population; and 
 sixteen cities in that state are operating under charters framed 
 in this way. The same plan was adopted in the constitution 
 of Washington in 1889 for cities of over 20,000 population, 
 in Minnesota by constitutional amendment in 1898; and in 
 Colorado in 1902 for every city of over 2000 population. A 
 similar procedure was followed by the legislature of Oregon 
 for the city of Portland in 1901, and a constitutional amend- 
 ment authorizing all cities in that state to enact and amend 
 their municipal charters was adopted in 1906. The same 
 plan is adopted in the program of the National Municipal 
 League for cities of over 25,000 population. 
 
 This system of "home-rule" charters secures to the cities 
 a large element of freedom from legislative interference. But 
 the experience of St. Louis, where police, excise, and election 
 administration has been placed in the hands of state appointed 
 officials, on the ground that these are state and not municipal 
 interests, shows that it may not altogether abolish it. On 
 the other hand, if these matters are also excluded from legis- 
 lative action, there is a serious danger that municipal auton- 
 omy may be carried so far as to impair the sovereignty of 
 the state, as has been urged by Governor Gage, of California. 
 It should also be noted that this system tends to increase the 
 confusion and complexity of the law on municipal govern-
 
 32 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ment. In practice, too, there has sometimes been a long 
 delay in securing the adoption of a charter under this process. 
 The first charter submitted for Denver was rejected, and a 
 second was framed and adopted with too little consideration. 
 In Minneapolis, four proposed charters have failed of rati- 
 fication, and the old discredited system continues in opera- 
 tion. 
 
 These considerations, and the frequent misrule and corrup- 
 tion in municipal government, make clear that the complete 
 independence of the city from the state is not a satisfac- 
 tory remedy for legislative interference. And while restric- 
 tions on special legislation and local charter conventions for 
 the larger cities are steps in the right direction, the limitation 
 on legislative control which they involve must be supplemented 
 by the fuller development of other methods of control, which 
 will be free from the evils that have accompanied the excessive 
 dependence on the legislature. What these methods should 
 be may be suggested by an examination of other forms of 
 control already in existence. 
 
 JUDICIAL CONTROL 
 
 To a considerable extent municipal officials are subject 
 to the control of the judicial authorities. Suits may be 
 brought against municipal corporations to enforce contract 
 rights, and to some extent for damages due to negligence on 
 the part of the agents of the municipality. Suits for damages 
 may also be brought against municipal officials for acts per- 
 formed without warrant of law. Municipal officials are also 
 subject to criminal prosecution, not only for purely private 
 acts, but also for misconduct in connection with their official 
 duties. In addition to these judicial remedies to redress 
 wrongful acts, the courts also exercise some preventive control 
 over the acts of officials through the issue of writs of man- 
 damus, injunction, certiorari, habeas corpus, quo warranto, 
 and the like by which they enforce statutory provisions 
 governing the powers and duties of these officials.
 
 ADMINISTKATIVE PROBLEMS 33 
 
 There is little or no opposition to this judicial control, and 
 almost the only criticism made of it is that it is not always 
 adequate to meet the situation. Criminal prosecutions de- 
 pend for their success on the action of local prosecuting 
 officers, local juries, and local judges, who may have close 
 political relations with the officials under trial; but recent 
 events in different parts of the country speak well for the 
 working of the local machinery of criminal justice. Other 
 difficulties arise from the precautions of our judicial system 
 in favor of persons accused of crime, which add to the diffi- 
 culties of conviction, and often secure acquittal or a new 
 trial on a technical appeal to a higher court. And in the 
 exercise of control through special writs, judges are extremely 
 careful not to interfere with the discretionary powers of admin- 
 istrative officials, even when these may have been clearly 
 abused. Evidently there is need for some further develop- 
 ment of state control. Something may perhaps be done in 
 strengthening the judicial powers in this direction; but some- 
 thing of a different nature must be devised to exercise the 
 supervision heretofore so badly attempted through the 
 detailed legislative control, whose abandonment has been 
 urged. 
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE CONTROL 
 
 It remains to examine the supervision exercised by executive 
 and administrative officers of the central state governments. 
 Fifty years ago or less no such supervision existed over 
 municipal officials, nor was there any effective administrative 
 supervision even of local officials, such as sheriffs and prosecu- 
 ting attorneys, who were clearly and directly subordinate 
 agents of the state governments. In England from the time of 
 the Normans to the Tudors the important local officers had 
 been both appointed by the Crown and closely supervised 
 in their actions by the Privy Council. But the internal con- 
 flicts of the seventeenth century resulted in breaking up the 
 machinery of administrative control, although the principal
 
 34 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 local officials continued to be appointed by the central govern- 
 ment. This system was brought over to the American col- 
 onies; but here it was completely decentralized by substi- 
 tuting local election for central appointment, while the regime 
 of no administrative supervision was continued. 
 
 Compared with conditions in continental Europe or with 
 those in Great Britain at the present time, or even with our 
 own national administration, central administrative control 
 of local officials in the American states is still very limited; 
 and this is particularly so in the case of municipal officials. 
 Nevertheless, there has been some development in this direc- 
 tion from the conditions during the first half of the nineteenth 
 century; and an understanding of this development and 
 the present situation may serve to indicate some features 
 of our future policy. In this examination attention will be 
 given to administrative supervision not only over municipal 
 officials, but over all local officials established and authorized 
 by the states. 
 
 Such supervision first appeared and has been furthest 
 developed in connection with educational administration. 
 Here decentralization was carried to the extreme in the petty 
 school district; but over the local school authorities there is 
 now in all of the states a superintendent of public instruction, 
 a board of education, or other central authority. The powers 
 of those state educational officials vary to some extent; but 
 in most states they have control over the distribution of state 
 school funds, direct the county supervision of schools, exer- 
 cise control over the qualifications and training of teachers, 
 and receive reports from all local school officers. In some 
 states their powers are more extensive, most of all in New 
 York, where the commissioner of education exercises super- 
 vision over elementary, secondary, and higher education; 
 while everywhere the state officials wield a large advisory 
 influence beyond their compulsory powers. 
 
 Another field of state administrative supervision of local 
 officials is that of matters affecting the public health. Most
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 35 
 
 of the states have a state board of health, which act as bureaus 
 of information and advice to local health officers; and in 
 certain cases of delinquency can compel the local officers 
 to take action. 
 
 In a similar way local charitable and correctional institu- 
 tions are, in some of the larger states, brought under the 
 inspection of state boards; which exercise an important 
 advisory influence over both local authorities and the legis- 
 lature, and in some cases may require the local officials to 
 remedy serious defects or to introduce improvements. 
 
 Some steps have also been taken in establishing adminis- 
 trative supervision over local assessing officers. Most of 
 the states now have state boards of equalization, which revise 
 the total assessed valuation of local districts, so as to appor- 
 tion the state property tax more equitably. In a number 
 of states, certain property formerly assessed by local officers 
 is now assessed by a state authority. And in a few states, 
 notably Wisconsin and Indiana, state tax commissioners are 
 given effective powers of supervision over local assessing 
 officers in assessing property even for local taxation. 
 
 A fairly uniform line of development has been followed in 
 connection with such state officials. When first established 
 they are only authorized to collect information and make 
 recommendations. Then this authority is made more effec- 
 tive by empowering them to require reports and by enlarging 
 their powers and means of inspection. This is followed by 
 some negative or preventive control, by the power to establish 
 regulations, and in some cases by authority to use compulsory 
 processes or remove delinquent local officials. 
 
 It is generally recognized that the supervision of such 
 state authorities as have been noted has worked for the im- 
 provement of public administration in the fields under their 
 control. Even where they have only informational and 
 advisory functions, something has been accomplished; and 
 more has been done where their powers and means are larger. 
 They have had two distinct advantages over the legislatures
 
 36 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and legislative committees. In the first place, by specializa- 
 tion of functions and longer service they become to some 
 extent at least experts in the particular subject ; in the second 
 place, partisan influences have been to a large extent excluded, 
 and the control exercised has not been abused for partisan 
 ends. 
 
 Would not a further development of such administrative 
 supervision in municipal matters be advisable? Does not 
 the existence of so many associations of municipal officials, 
 for the purpose of collecting and comparing information about 
 their work, show that in this field as in others, while "power 
 may be decentralized, knowledge to be most useful must be 
 centralized"? 1 The collection and publication of municipal 
 information can be more effectively done by an official state 
 authority than by purely voluntary action; and the recom- 
 mendations of such a central state bureau, based on adequate 
 and accurate data, would serve to solve many of the diffi- 
 culties of municipal administration. 
 
 Besides the work of information and advice, there are some 
 branches of municipal government where further state admin- 
 istrative supervision would operate to the advantage both 
 of the cities and of the state as a whole. In the field of mu- 
 nicipal finances the task of securing satisfactory data can only 
 be accomplished on the basis of scientific and uniform method 
 of keeping accounts in all of the cities. In most American 
 cities municipal accounts and financial reports are still unintel- 
 ligible to the ordinary citizen; and even where an under- 
 standable system is adopted in a particular city it is likely 
 to be of little use in making comparisons with other cities 
 using other systems. It is only on the basis of a uniform 
 system that accurate and comparable information can be 
 secured; and this can be secured only through a general law 
 enforced by state officials. Some progress has been made in 
 this direction in a few states. Wyoming for a number of years 
 has had an examiner of public accounts, exercising powers 
 *J. S. Mill, Representative Government.
 
 ADMINISTRATIVE PROBLEMS 37 
 
 over the financial accounts and reports of local officials similar 
 to those in most states exercised over the accounts of banking 
 and insurance companies. More recently Massachusetts and 
 New York have enacted statutes providing for uniform finan- 
 cial reports from cities; while within a few years Ohio and 
 Iowa have enacted effective laws for uniform municipal 
 accounting under the direction of the state auditor. Similar 
 measures are being discussed in other states; and should 
 be encouraged. 
 
 Another field where there is special need for state adminis- 
 trative supervision is that of the police. The courts have 
 repeatedly recognized that in the control over the police, 
 municipal officials are acting not as local authorities, but as 
 agents of the state. And this view has often been made the 
 excuse for vesting the police administration of some cities 
 completely in state appointed authorities. This special 
 treatment of particular cities cannot be defended on any 
 general principle ; but the judicial view of the state's authority 
 and the interests of the state as a whole in an effective and 
 honest police administration do warrant a general system 
 of supervision in this field. This is not introducing any novel 
 idea into our system of government, nor does it require any 
 elaborate system of new officials to put it into effect. All 
 that is necessary is to energize one of the oldest factors in 
 our system of local government. Make it the specific duty 
 of the county sheriffs, the responsible peace officers, to inspect 
 the local police within their jurisdiction, and to report 
 periodically to the governor of the state; and give to 
 the governors in all states a power, now partially given in 
 some, 1 to remove delinquent sheriffs or other local police 
 officers. 
 
 To summarize: The demand for municipal home rule 
 
 should be made more specific and more definite. It must be 
 
 made clear that what is wanted is, not a revolution involving 
 
 the complete separation of the cities from the state, but a 
 
 1 New York, Michigan, Wisconsin.
 
 38 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 larger freedom in matters of local concern from the restrictions 
 of detailed municipal legislation, while retaining the control 
 of the judiciary and asking for the assistance and supervision 
 of state officers in securing the highest and the best municipal 
 administration in the world.
 
 Ill 
 
 THE RELATION OF CIVIL SERVICE REFORM TO 
 MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 1 
 
 THE problems of municipal administration present a mani- 
 fold and complex variety of topics. Some are political, such 
 as the regulation of nomination and election methods. Some, 
 dealing with the machinery of local organization and the 
 relations of the city to the State government, are adminis- 
 trative. Others involve questions of economic policy as to 
 the proper scope of municipal activity. While still others 
 embrace in themselves a wide variety of problems in engi- 
 neering, sanitary science, and other technical subjects. 
 
 It is the purpose of this paper to consider only one aspect 
 of the administrative problems, the application of the prin- 
 ciples of civil service reform in the organization of municipal 
 government. These principles hardly need to be enumerated 
 here. But they may be briefly summarized as the selection 
 of public officials and employees on the basis of their ability 
 and fitness for their public duties, rather than as rewards 
 or opportunities for private or party service; and the main- 
 tenance of the public service on the basis of honesty and the 
 highest efficiency. 
 
 That any discussion or argument in support of these prin- 
 ciples is necessary is of itself evidence of a strange miscon- 
 ception of the purposes of municipal government. And it 
 is surely enough to establish the fundamental principles to 
 point to the laws creating public positions and prescribing 
 their duties. These at least assume that the public servants 
 are provided to perform public functions. 2 And the hardiest 
 
 1 An address delivered at the Annual Meeting of the National Civil 
 Service Reform League, Milwaukee, Wis., Dec. 15, 1905. 
 
 2 The standard treatise on the law of public officers states that it is 
 the duty of the governor to see that fit and competent officials are ap- 
 pointed by him. Mechem, Public Officers, Sec. 590. And the same 
 principle must apply also to municipal appointments. 
 
 39
 
 40 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 spoils politicians have not yet ventured to place their 
 principle "To the victors belong the spoils" openly on the 
 statute book. 
 
 Nevertheless, it is only too clear, that the plain intent of 
 the law is frequently and systematically evaded in most 
 of our large cities. Appointments are made of persons who 
 have little or no competence for their positions, as rewards 
 for past or future political services. And to make room for 
 such appointments experienced officials and employees are 
 removed. As a result the public service is notoriously ineffi- 
 cient and at times almost demoralized. The inherent dis- 
 honesty to the community in such appointments makes it 
 an easy step to more flagrant neglect of duty and corruption 
 of the worst sort. While the whole system tends to debauch 
 and corrupt the electorate by offering places for votes. 
 
 Looking simply at its direct effect on municipal adminis- 
 tration, a brief analysis will show the importance of efficient 
 and expert officials. Municipal administration is already a 
 complicated series of technical services. To maintain order 
 and security a police force must be maintained, under semi- 
 military discipline, requiring qualifications of physical strength, 
 courage, and honesty for any effective work. To prevent 
 destruction by fire, there must be a fire department, whose 
 members should have the highest physical skill and technical 
 knowledge of the intricate apparatus used. To safeguard 
 the health of the community there must be a department 
 with expert sanitarians, chemists, and bacteriologists. To 
 provide the essential conveniences of city life there must be 
 civil engineers to lay out streets and construct pavements 
 and sewers, hydraulic engineers to manage water works, and 
 sanitary engineers to solve the problems of garbage and sewage 
 disposal. To lay out and care for the public parks there must 
 be landscape architects and 'gardeners. To administer public 
 charity wisely and not wastefully requires trained students 
 of practical philanthropy; and in public hospitals a corps of 
 physicians and trained nurses. To carry out the policy of
 
 CIVIL SERVICE REFORM 41 
 
 public education there must be not only competent elemen- 
 tary teachers, but in the high schools those with the highest 
 specialized education, and over all efficient educational ad- 
 ministrators. To keep track of the finances in these various 
 fields of expenditure demands a force of expert accountants; 
 and to equitably assess taxes there should be an equally 
 expert body of assessors. While to deal with the many legal 
 questions which arise, every large city must employ a number 
 of attorneys, specially versed in questions of municipal law. 
 
 Our cities do not have to wait for municipal street railways 
 to be face to face with most serious problems of technical 
 administration. Even now the corps of municipal officials 
 and employees represents every main division of industrial 
 and professional life. Lawyers, teachers, accountants, engi- 
 neers of almost every sort, besides executive administrators, 
 are essential to carry out the accepted functions of municipal 
 government. 
 
 Positions such as these cannot safely be filled on any 
 such basis as political service. Each field is a special pro- 
 fession requiring years of training; and those who are most 
 competent have too many opportunities in private business 
 to devote much time to political campaigning; while they 
 are also likely to hesitate about accepting a municipal position 
 with the uncertain tenure of a political appointment. More- 
 over, the municipal service for most of these professions is 
 of itself a specialized branch, where the highest degree of 
 efficiency can only be secured by continued practice. A 
 city attorney who serves only for a few years cannot be so 
 competent in the law on municipal questions as a corpora- 
 tion lawyer who devotes his life to corporation law is on that 
 subject. And a civil engineer who serves for a while as a city 
 officer and then in railroad building is not likely to be either 
 the most competent city engineer or the most competent 
 railroad engineer. What is needed is a class of municipal 
 specialists in law, accounting, engineering, and other fields 
 of action. And these can only be secured under a system
 
 42 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 of selection which excludes political motives and insures 
 a tenure based only on efficiency and competence. 
 
 Conditions in this regard are different from those in earlier 
 periods. It has sometimes seemed to me that there was 
 a certain harmony between the principle of rotation in office 
 and conditions which prevailed in this country during the 
 first half of the nineteenth century. While the country was 
 being settled there was a constant movement of population 
 from place to place and frequent changes of occupation. 
 Short terms of office and frequent changes were then in accord 
 with the restless customs and practices of the people in their 
 private business. And it might have been argued that an 
 officeholder who wished to hold an office for many years 
 doubtless lacked the ability to take advantage of opportunities 
 for bettering his situation. 
 
 But these conditions are no longer in force. At the pres- 
 ent time the jack-of-all-trades is almost certainly so because 
 he lacks the ability to become master of one. The success- 
 ful man in private business is the specialist who devotes his 
 life to one purpose. And what is true of the individual in 
 private life is true also for those who hold positions in the 
 municipal or other public service. The largest results will 
 come by division of labor and concentration of effort. The 
 best public servants will be those who give the longest time 
 to the public service ; and that city or State will get the best 
 results which looks for the most capable men and keeps 
 them in its service so as to secure the advantage of their 
 increasing experience. 
 
 Some steps have been taken to apply the principles laid 
 down to the municipal service. Systems of civil service 
 examinations have been established in a number of cities 
 applying to most of the -subordinate positions. Appoint- 
 ments to these positions are based on the results of open 
 competitive examinations and probationary service; with 
 the result that these places are to a large extent taken "out 
 of politics." In some other cities the police and fire depart-
 
 CIVIL SERVICE REFORM 43 
 
 ments are more or less protected against political appoint- 
 ments. And more generally school-teachers are selected 
 with comparatively little reference to political influence. 
 
 Into the details of these systems it is not necessary to go 
 here. They have placed a smaller or larger part of the 
 municipal employees on a sound administrative footing; 
 and although the law is sometimes evaded by hostile officials, 
 the results have been a great improvement in the standard 
 of municipal work. In other cities efforts towards the same 
 end are being made. And the extensions of these systems 
 as rapidly and as far as possible is one of the most important 
 municipal reforms at the present time. 
 
 But what has been accomplished in most of these cases 
 applies mainly to the subordinate posts in the municipal 
 service. These are by far the largest in number. But the 
 important positions, and above all the officers as distinguished 
 from the employees of our cities, are still chosen largely or 
 mainly for political reasons. And until these too are chosen 
 solely for ability, competence, and honesty, no satisfactory 
 municipal administration can be secured. 
 
 Political appointments to the higher posts affect the 
 character of municipal work in two ways. Such officials 
 are likely to seek to evade whatever regulations are estab- 
 lished for the subordinate service so as to reward their political 
 supporters; and in this way they prove a constant obstacle 
 in the application of the merit system so far as introduced. 
 But of even more importance is the fact that it is in the case 
 of the higher officials that incompetence and inexperience 
 proves most costly to the city. Some gain is made when 
 the clerical and routine work is well done. But much more 
 is lost if serious blunders are made in the main plans, or in 
 the direction of their execution. 
 
 Incompetent city engineers may easily double the neces- 
 sary cost of an important scheme of public improvement. 
 City comptrollers have generally had so little knowledge of 
 accounting that it is almost impossible for any one to under-
 
 44 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 stand their financial reports. City attorneys who know 
 more politics than law are likely to recommend useless liti- 
 gation and in other cases to surrender the legal rights of the 
 city. And city clerks who are changed every few years can- 
 not perform one of their main functions as a source of infor- 
 mation on the previous actions of the municipal government. 
 
 How can these principles of civil service reform be applied 
 to these higher municipal officials? The methods employed 
 in selecting employees for subordinate positions will hardly 
 be in every detail the most effective for these more impor- 
 tant posts. Something more is needed than a test of their 
 technical knowledge. What is wanted are those who know 
 best how to apply their knowledge in a constructive manner, 
 and those who have the peculiar form of ability known as 
 executive or business capacity. Moreover, for these posts the 
 test of brief probationary appointments cannot well be applied. 
 For those best fitted for such places will be already engaged in 
 similar work, and are not likely to abandon a permanent posi- 
 tion for a probationary appointment in the public service. 
 
 These difficulties require some changes in methods. But 
 such changes of detail are by no means impossible or incon- 
 sistent with the main principles of the merit system. The 
 important point is to find the methods best adapted for 
 various classes of offices. 
 
 One of the first steps that must be taken in many cities is 
 to take these higher administrative posts out of the class of 
 elective offices. Popular election necessarily introduces 
 political factors into the choice of officers, and for officers 
 who have political functions to perform popular election is 
 essential in a democratic government. But city clerks, 
 city attorneys, city comptrollers, commissioners of public 
 works, and city engineers have no political functions to per- 
 form. Their work not only has no relation to national 
 politics; it has no relation to municipal politics. Their 
 duties are strictly administrative and call for the same quali- 
 fications whether a city votes for or against municipal owner-
 
 CIVIL SERVICE REFORM 45 
 
 ship, and whether it votes for or against a "wide open" 
 saloon policy. And whatever other method is employed, 
 it is clear that popular election is not the best method to test 
 technical and administrative ability. Moreover, by remov- 
 ing such officers from the elective list, the attention of the 
 voters will be concentrated on the personal merits of the 
 candidates for the political offices, and better results may 
 be hoped for the latter under such conditions. 
 
 But appointments, whether by mayor or council, will be 
 made by political officials; and, so far as discretion is left 
 to them, there is still the danger that political motives will 
 be a controlling factor. To reduce this danger, another 
 step, which is still within the purposes of this Association, 
 is to eliminate the official recognition of national parties in 
 municipal elections. I am not at all confident that it is 
 possible by law to prevent the national party organizations 
 from taking an active part in local campaigns. But at least 
 the law should not recognize them officially, and should re- 
 quire each candidate for municipal office to appear on the 
 ballot simply as an individual. This will not eliminate 
 politics, or even national politics, from municipal elections. 
 But it will tend to reduce these factors to some extent. 
 
 In the next place, appointments to the higher positions 
 should be for an indefinite term. The power of removal 
 must be retained for such offices, as a means of control over 
 incompetent officials; and this will make it possible for 
 removals to be made for political reasons. But to create 
 a vacancy by removal is at least somewhat more difficult 
 than to find one by the expiration of a definite term. And 
 the law at least will stand for the principle that the competent 
 officials are to be retained so long as they perform their duties 
 satisfactorily. This rule has been established in the new 
 Indiana municipal code. It also applies to most of the heads 
 of departments in New York City; and is probably respon- 
 sible for the retention of one commissioner appointed by 
 Mayor Low in the succeeding administration.
 
 46 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 These various provisions, it is believed, will do something 
 toward reducing political influences in filling the higher 
 offices. But they can hardly be expected to secure their 
 disappearance and the selection of these officers mainly from 
 considerations of ability and experience. For that purpose, 
 some provision must be made for a systematic investigation 
 of the qualifications of various applicants, so as to determine 
 who is best fitted for the place. 
 
 Such an investigation should, however, be somewhat 
 different from the examinations for subordinate places. 
 It should test not only technical knowledge, but also practical 
 experience and constructive ability. Such tests can be 
 applied. They are now used in many cases by the United 
 States Civil Service Commission, for technical and profes- 
 sional positions in the national administration. They are 
 used to a large extent in the system for regulating admission 
 to the higher branches of the Paris municipal service. In 
 the latter case, the more important part of the test for candi- 
 dates is a detailed report on a special topic within the field 
 of his work. The same idea is recognized in our universities 
 in conferring the degree of doctor of philosophy, where the 
 thesis showing the candidate's personal research and con- 
 structive ability, is of at least equal importance with the 
 general examination. In the same way, candidates for the 
 higher municipal offices could be asked to submit statements 
 of their practical experience and some examples of their 
 constructive work. 
 
 Moreover, in order that practical experience may be given 
 its full advantage, the competition for these higher municipal 
 posts should not be limited to residents of the city, but should 
 be thrown open to any one. Already this rule is largely 
 recognized in the selection of school superintendents, and it 
 is generally felt that these are the most capable and efficient 
 of our higher municipal officials. In England, vacancies in 
 such positions as town clerk and borough engineer are ad- 
 vertised and applications are made from all over the country.
 
 CIVIL SERVICE REFORM 47 
 
 In Germany, it has even happened that a mayor has been 
 chosen in Berlin on the basis of his record in a smaller city. 
 By making these higher positions open to all candidates, 
 the large cities can get the benefit of experience and ability 
 proven in actual service. 
 
 Another feature of the regulations for the higher munici- 
 pal service in Paris might well be adopted for the higher 
 offices in this country. This is an examination in the system 
 of public administration. Very many of 'our public officials 
 or indeed of the best educated citizens have no clear idea 
 of even the main principles of our system of local govern- 
 ment. Yet they must act in accordance with the laws es- 
 tablishing the government ; and in their ignorance often make 
 serious mistakes which lead to protracted litigation. A defi- 
 nite knowledge of our system of administration on the part of 
 public officials would save our cities much trouble and expense. 
 
 By such methods a merit system can be applied to the 
 higher posts, as well as the subordinate places, in the mu- 
 nicipal service. And these reforms are among the most 
 important needed in municipal administration at the present 
 time. Without them no city can successfully perform the 
 functions it is now undertaking. And without them there 
 can be no safe extension of municipal activities into new fields. 
 
 Nor does the merit system involve any departure from 
 the fundamental principles of American government. On 
 the contrary, it is the most direct method of putting them 
 into effect. As one writer has well said: 
 
 "This system is democratic, for it gives every citizen 
 an equal opportunity to participate in the public service 
 according to his fitness. It is economical, because it brings 
 into office competent persons who work for their wages and 
 are not required to spend half the city's time 'hustling' 
 for votes or organizing political clubs. It is scientific because, 
 through permanence of official tenure, it develops specialists 
 in every department of city administration." * 
 1 D. F. Wilcox, The American City, p. 300.
 
 IV 
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 1 
 
 AMERICAN municipal government has its historical origin 
 in the chartered boroughs or municipal corporations estab- 
 lished in several of the English colonies during the seventeenth 
 and first half of the eighteenth centuries. The hundred and 
 thirty years since the end of the colonial period has wrought 
 an enormous development in the scale of municipal activities, 
 has seen the addition of many new municipal functions, and 
 has been accompanied by many changes in municipal or- 
 ganization. But the institutional history from the colonial 
 corporations to the cities of to-day is continuous, and the 
 influence of the former on the latter is clearly visible. An 
 account of the organization and activities of these colonial 
 boroughs should therefore have the same interest to the 
 student of municipal government, that the town meeting 
 has to the student of rural institutions. It forms in fact 
 a necessary introduction to any history of municipal develop- 
 ment in the United States. 
 
 A complete explanation of the ultimate origin of the colonial 
 borough 2 and hence of the American city would re- 
 
 1 Reprinted from Municipal Affairs, II, 341 (September, 1898). 
 It may be noted that this original publication antedated by several 
 years the article on "Municipal Corporations" by Professor Henry 
 Wade Rogers, in the Yale bicentenary volume on Two Centuries' Growth 
 of American Law, which article contains some striking resemblances to 
 this paper both in subject-matter and foot-note references. 
 
 1 The name "borough" is used as a generic term for all of the colonial 
 municipal corporations; although, as will be noticed, some of them 
 (in fact all the most important of them) were called cities from the first. 
 The name " borough " is preferred, because from the point of view of the 
 student of institutions they were English boroughs created in the English 
 colonies. The name "city " has no institutional connotation in connection 
 with these corporations; none of them had the characteristic feature 
 
 48
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 49 
 
 quire a history of the development of the English borough. 
 The general outline of this is, however, familiar to students 
 of English history; and at any rate it is not possible to give 
 here more than the briefest outline of the English borough 
 as it existed in the seventeenth century. The typical con- 
 stitution, general as early as the reign of Henry VII, is 
 described by Bishop Stubbs as a "close corporation of a 
 mayor, alderman, and council with precisely defined organiza- 
 tion and numbers not indeed uniform, but of the same 
 general conformation possessing a new character denoted 
 in the name of ' corporation ' in its legal sense." l In each 
 borough there was also a number of freemen in whom were 
 vested the right of voting for members of Parliament, and 
 who had certain exclusive trading privileges and exemptions 
 from tolls and market dues privileges which in some in- 
 stances were of no little pecuniary importance. The powers 
 and functions of the corporations varied widely in the different 
 communities. But in general the local matters in charge 
 of the borough officials were not of vast importance. The 
 church-wardens, overseers of the poor, and overseers of 
 highways had the same powers in the parishes within a 
 borough as in rural parishes. The problems of street pav- 
 ing, street lighting, drainage, and water supply had not at 
 this time been forced on the attention of the people through 
 density of population. In the time of Charles II, there was 
 no town in England outside London with a population of 
 over 30,000, and only four provincial towns contained so many 
 as 10,000 inhabitants. 2 The management of local police, 
 the judicial administration, the direction of markets, and 
 the charge of the ancient town property sum up the local 
 
 of the English city a cathedral church, as the residence of a bishop 
 and the use of the name " borough " will serve to emphasize the fact that 
 the colonial institution had a much closer resemblance to its English 
 prototype than to the American institution which a century of evolution 
 has developed. 
 
 1 Constitutional History of England, III, 577. 
 
 2 Macaulay, History of England, I, 261.
 
 50 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 interests under the control of the borough governments 
 even in the larger towns. In many of the small towns which 
 had been created boroughs simply for the purpose of controll- 
 ing Parliament, the corporation had no local duties whatever, 
 the election of members to Parliament constituting their 
 sole function. 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF COLONIAL BOROUGHS 1 
 
 The earliest mention of boroughs in American history is in 
 connection with the first Virginia Assembly. The members 
 of this assembly were called " burgesses," and the districts 
 which they represented were called "boroughs." Jamestown 
 was a borough, so also were Henrico and Bermuda Hundred; 
 in all, by the summer of 1619, there were eleven boroughs 
 in the colony of Virginia entitled to send members to the 
 colonial assembly. 2 These boroughs, however, were in no 
 way municipal corporations; they were not even local 
 government organizations; they were election districts for 
 members to the assembly, and nothing more. The use of 
 the name " borough " indicates how completely subordinate 
 the local functions of most English boroughs had become in 
 comparison with its position as a parliamentary district. 
 The name "burgess" remained the title of members of the 
 
 1 LIST OF COLONIAL BOROUGHS 
 
 Agamenticus, Me. Perth Amboy, N.J., chartered 1718. 
 
 (now York, Me.), chartered 1641. Bristol, Perm., chartered 1720. 
 
 Kittery, Me., chartered 1647. Williamsburg, Va., chartered 1722. 
 
 New York, N.Y., chartered 1686. N. Brunswick, N. J., chartered 1730. 
 
 Albany, N.Y., chartered 1686. Burlington, N.J., chartered 1733. 
 
 Germantown, Penn., chartered 1687. Norfolk, Va., chartered 1736. 
 
 Philadelphia, Penn., chartered 1691. Richmond, Va., chartered 1742. 
 
 Chester, Penn., chartered 1701. Elizabeth, N.J., chartered 1740. 
 
 Westchester, N.Y., chartered 170?* Lancaster, Penn., chartered 1742. 
 
 Bath, N.C., chartered 1705. Trenton, N.J., chartered 1746. 
 Annapolis, Md., chartered 1708. 
 
 * The Colonial Laws of New York show that Westchester was a town as late 
 as 1700, but was a borough by 1705. 
 
 2 Stith, History of Virginia, pp. 160-161.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPOKATIONS IN THE COLONIES 51 
 
 Virginia Assembly even after the representation was based 
 on the county, and the lower house of the Virginia legislature 
 was called the " House of Burgesses " until the Revolution. 
 Governor Winthrop of Massachusetts, in his Journal, 
 mentions as one reason why the province of Maine was not 
 admitted to the Confederation of the United Colonies of New 
 England, that "They had lately made Acomenticus (a poor 
 village) a corporation, and had made a tailor their mayor." * 
 This borough of Acomenticus or Agamenticus is the 
 first instance of the establishment of the English municipal 
 corporation in America. The first settlement had been 
 made at Agamenticus by Sir Fernando Gorges in 1624, and 
 by 1630 the place had a population of about one hundred 
 and fifty. 2 The grant to Gorges had authorized him to in- 
 corporate boroughs, and on April 10, 1641, he issued a char- 
 ter on the English model. 3 In less than a year he issued 
 another charter, erecting the borough of Agamenticus into 
 a city by the name of "Georgeana," 4 and the mayor, recorder 
 and alderman were duly selected for the new city. 5 In 1647 
 Gorges incorporated the village of Kittery as a borough,' 
 and a decided movement toward the founding of boroughs 
 in this colony at least would seem on first sight to have been 
 inaugurated. In fact, however, these boroughs were little 
 more than paper corporations. The charters of Gorges were 
 almost ignored by the actual settlers, who made arrange- 
 ments for their local government to suit themselves. 7 And 
 in 1652, on the union of Maine with Massachusetts, the 
 charters lost even their legal standing. The boroughs were 
 organized under the Massachusetts town system, and the name 
 
 1 John Winthrop, Journal, II, 121. 
 
 2 W. D. Williamson, History of Maine, I, 267. 
 '"Charter" in Hazard, Historical Collections, I, 470. 
 4 Ibid., 480. 
 
 1 G. A. Emery, History of Georgeana and York, gives a list of the 
 first city officers. 
 
 W. D. Williamson, History of Maine, I, 346. 
 7 Emery, History of Georgeana and York, p. 41.
 
 52 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 of Agamenticus was changed once more, this time to York, 
 which name it has retained ever since. 1 York was one of 
 the two principal towns of Maine during the colonial period. 
 Had it remained a borough, its development must have been 
 of great value to this study. As it is, the charters of Aga- 
 menticus and Georgeana are of interest mainly as curiosities. 
 
 The Corporation of New York the first borough with 
 an active existence dates from June 12, 1665, when a proc- 
 lamation issued by Governor Nicols declared that "the 
 inhabitants of New York . . . are and shall be for ever 
 accounted, nominated and established as one Body, Politique 
 and Corporate." 2 The municipal history of New Amster- 
 dam, and the long struggle between the inhabitants and the 
 governors sent over by the Dutch West India Company are 
 of interest to the local historian, but have little bearing on 
 the borough government of New York. It may be noted, 
 however, that in 1653 the inhabitants on Manhattan Island 
 secured the forms of government of a Dutch city ; 3 and that 
 in 1658 the acknowledgment of the right of the retiring 
 officers to name a double list of nominees, from whom the 
 governor was required to select the city officials for the 
 following year, established a limited degree of local inde- 
 pendence. The fact that New Amsterdam had the govern- 
 mental organization of a Dutch city undoubtedly had its 
 weight in the immediate establishment of New York as a cor- 
 poration; but in other respects the influence of Dutch in- 
 stitutions on the municipal development of New York seems 
 to have been but slight. 
 
 Although created a corporation in 1665, New York did 
 not at this time receive a charter. The mayor, aldermen, 
 and sheriff were appointed from year to year by the governor 
 of the province, and they exercised such powers as seemed 
 advisable to the authorities. Many of the municipal usages 
 
 1 W. D. Williamson, History of Maine, I, 346. 
 
 1 " Proclamation," in Documentary History of New York, I, 390. 
 
 8 Documentary History of New York, I, 387.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 53 
 
 were allowed to remain uncertain, and much power over the 
 concerns of the city remained in the hands of the governor. 
 Governor Andros, for example, took a personal interest and 
 exercised a personal supervision of municipal affairs, and 
 did much to beautify the city. 1 
 
 The need was felt for establishing the municipal govern- 
 ment on a firmer basis, and when, in 1683, Governor Dongan 
 arrived in the colony, the mayor and aldermen presented 
 a petition for a charter, confirming their "ancient customs, 
 privileges, and immunities," with certain additional officers, 
 and providing that the aldermen should be elected by the 
 inhabitants instead of appointed by the governor. 2 Dongan 
 agreed to allow the wishes of the petitioners to go into effect 
 at once, but declined to issue a charter until he heard from 
 the Duke of York. In 1686 the mayor and recorder sub- 
 mitted a draft of the desired charter to the governor, and 
 this was allowed April 27, 1686, was duly signed by the 
 governor, and sealed with the old provincial seal sent out in 
 1669. This charter, based partly on existing customs, some 
 of which were affected by the peculiar conditions of a colony, 
 but in the main similar to the charters of English boroughs, has 
 continued to be the basis of the municipal laws, rights, privi- 
 leges, public property, and franchises of the city. That it 
 was called a city in the charter instead of a borough was 
 probably because it had been called a city when under the 
 Dutch, and had, under its new name, continued to be called 
 a city after the English conquest. 
 
 In 1730 New York received another charter from Governor 
 Montgomerie. The Dongan charter, although not issued 
 until over a year after the Duke of York had become King 
 of England, had been sealed with the ducal seal instead of 
 the royal seal sent over after the death of Charles II. It 
 was feared that this invalidated the Dongan charter, 3 and 
 
 1 Memorial History of New York, I, 397. 
 
 2 Documents relating to the Colonial History of New York, III, 337. 
 
 s See letters of Governors Bellomont and Hunter in Documents relat- 
 ing to the Colonial History of New York, IV, 812; V, 369.
 
 54 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 thoroughly to establish the municipal government of New 
 York on a legal basis the new charter was issued in 1730, 
 having been sent to England to receive the King's seal. 1 
 The Montgomerie charter made some important additions 
 to the powers of the corporation of New York. It remained 
 in force until 1836, except during the period of the British 
 occupation of the city from 1776 to 1784. It was confirmed 
 by the New York state constitution of 1777, but was modified 
 by state legislation after the Revolution. 
 
 Three months after granting the charter to New York, 
 Governor Dongan issued a charter of incorporation for the 
 city of Albany. The settlement at the head of navigation 
 on the Hudson River had existed, under various names, 
 since the first appearance of the Dutch West India Company 
 in North America. While Stuyvesant was governor of New 
 Netherlands, a local organization had been provided for this 
 trading post, 2 and when the English took possession in 1664 
 they did not disturb this, merely changing the name of the 
 place to Albany. In 1686 the settlement had grown so 
 large 3 that further provisions for local government were 
 necessary. The issue of the charter to New York pointed 
 out the form of government for which to apply, and Peter 
 Schuyler and Robert Livingston were commissioned to go 
 to New York to procure a charter. 4 The charter procured 
 was somewhat more detailed than the New York charter, 
 and contained a few different provisions. In the main, 
 however, it was a copy of the earlier instrument, and under 
 it the city of Albany was governed until long after the Revo- 
 lution, except for two years during the war. 5 
 
 The first charter of Philadelphia may have dated earlier 
 
 1 Memorial History of New York, II, 190. 
 
 2 Munsell, Annals of Albany, I, 189. 
 
 3 In 1689 the population of the county of Albany was 2016. Docu- 
 mentary History of New York, I, 690. Probably half of this at least 
 was in the town of Albany. 
 
 * J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, II, 88. 
 ' J. Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 275.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 55 
 
 than the Dongan charters to New York and Albany. The 
 location for the centre of trade and the political capital of 
 the new colony of Pennsylvania had been selected in 1683, 
 and in the same year the streets were laid out in the well- 
 known checkerboard style. On the 26th day of the fifth 
 month, 1684, a committee of the Provincial Council was 
 appointed to draw up a charter creating the Borough of 
 Philadelphia. 1 There is no record of the action of the com- 
 mittee, but the city charter of 1691 recites that the town of 
 Philadelphia had been previously erected into a borough. 
 No account remains of the government under the borough 
 charter or under the charter of 1691 ; and it seems probable 
 that after 1692 there was no local organization in existence 
 until in 1701 a new city charter was granted. 2 This was 
 substantially a revival of the charter of ten years before, 
 and under it the government of Philadelphia was conducted 
 until 1776. 
 
 Four other boroughs were incorporated in Pennsylvania 
 during the colonial period. The first of these, Germantown, 
 procured its charter from Perm in 1689; and in 1691 the new 
 organization went into effect. The German settlers, how- 
 ever, cared little for politics, and it was with difficulty that 
 the corporation maintained its existence. At last, in 1707, 
 they failed to find officers enough to serve, and thus forfeited 
 their charter. The town of Bristol, eighteen miles above 
 Philadelphia, on the Delaware, was established in 1697. 
 By the year 1720, the inhabitants thought it to their ad- 
 vantage to be incorporated, and a number of them petitioned 
 the governor of the province, Sir William Keith, for a borough 
 charter. 3 The petition was favorably considered, and a 
 charter was drafted and approved by the colonial board, 
 July 19, 1720. The sanction of the Crown was received with 
 
 1 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 4. 
 
 2 The existence of any charter prior to 1701 was for a long time con- 
 sidered a myth, but in 1887 the charter of 1691 was discovered, and that 
 it went into operation proved. Pennsylvania Magazine, XV, 345. 
 
 8 W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, pp. 29, 30.
 
 56 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the necessary letters patent on November 14. The two 
 other Pennsylvania boroughs of colonial times were Chester 
 and Lancaster, whose charters are dated respectively in 
 1701 and 1742. The charters for these four smaller boroughs 
 provided a simpler form of government than that established 
 in New York, Albany, and Philadelphia. Their influence 
 on the later development of local government institutions 
 in the United States has been as the foundation of the system 
 of "borough" government for the villages and smaller towns 
 of Pennsylvania, a most important factor in the local govern- 
 ment of that state. 
 
 In 1705 the city of Bath, N.C., was incorporated, 
 but this never became more than a mere hamlet. 1 The 
 borough of Westchester in New York was also incorporated 
 about this time, but did not become a place of much promi- 
 nence. A more important case is that of Annapolis, which re- 
 ceived its charter from Governor John Seymour, of Maryland, 
 on August 16, 1708. 2 In 1696 certain persons in the town 
 had been created by act of the assembly, a body corporate 
 and politic under the name of "Commissioners and trustees 
 for the port and town of Annapolis," with power to hold 
 courts and make by-laws. Governor Seymour proposed 
 a charter as early as 1704, but no measures being taken by 
 the assembly, at length he conferred the charter by virtue of 
 the prerogative of his office. 3 
 
 In Virginia the first attempt to introduce the borough as 
 a local government institution was by the Act of 1705, 4 
 which provided for the establishment of certain towns as 
 free burghs with merchant gilds, benchers of the gild hall, 
 and other features of the English mercantile gilds. The 
 attempt was not successful in the colony, and it was also 
 
 1 Moore, History of North Carolina. 
 
 * John Fiske, in his Civil Government in the U. S., calls Annapolis the 
 third incorporation in America, overlooking Albany, Germantown, 
 Chester, Westchester, and Bath, as well as the two in Maine. 
 
 s D. Ridgely, Annals of Annapolis, pp. 89, 110. 
 
 4 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, III, 404.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 57 
 
 opposed in England on the ground that the establishment 
 of towns tended to the encouragement of manufactures. 1 
 In 1710 Governor Spotswood, acting under instructions from 
 the Crown, issued a proclamation repealing the Act. It was 
 not until 1722 that a charter of incorporation was granted 
 in Virginia, when Williamsburg, the new capital of the colony, 
 was incorporated. In 1736 the town of Norfolk received 
 a borough charter from Governor William Gooch. Norfolk 
 had been first settled under the influence of the act for co- 
 habitation and encouragement of trade and manufacture, 
 passed in 1680. 2 In spite of the suspension of the act, the 
 town continued to grow, and in 1736 the population had so 
 increased that the inhabitants petitioned for a charter, 3 
 which when granted remained the basis of its local govern- 
 ment until the middle of the nineteenth century. Richmond 
 was also incorporated in 1742. 
 
 Five incorporating charters were granted in the colony of 
 New Jersey, to the "cities" of Perth Amboy (1718), New 
 Brunswick (1730), and Burlington (1733), and the "boroughs" 
 of Elizabeth (1740), and Trenton (1746). 4 One of the objects 
 aimed at in the incorporation of Perth Amboy was the pro- 
 motion of the town as a commercial centre in rivalry with 
 New York. The charter states that it is incorporated be- 
 cause "it is best situated for a place of trade and as a harbor 
 for shipping preferable to those in the provinces adjoining." 5 
 The development of a great commercial port also played its 
 part in the incorporation of New Brunswick, which was 
 made a city, because it stood " at the head of a fine navigable 
 river, and being the most convenient place for shipping of 
 the produce lying on the back thereof." 6 
 
 1 E. Ingle, Virginia Local Institutions, in Johns Hopkins University 
 Studies, III, 210. 
 
 2 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, II, 471. 
 
 3 Forrest, History of Norfolk, p. 49. 
 
 4 A. Scott in N.J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 151. 5 Ibid., p. 153. 
 8 New Brunswick charter; quoted by A. Scott in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., 
 
 IX, 153.
 
 58 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 A comparison of the charters issued to the "cities" of Perth 
 Amboy and New Brunswick with the charter granted to the 
 "borough" of Elizabeth shows clearly that the so-called 
 cities were in reality the same institution as the borough. 
 The three charters are practically identical in the organiza- 
 tion provided, and in the allotment and distribution of powers. 
 The two West Jersey charters (Burlington and Trenton) 
 possess independent characteristics. They have many single 
 features in common with the Philadelphia charters, but have 
 also many distinctive features, each peculiar to itself. The 
 charter of Trenton after being in operation for three years 
 and three months was surrendered (April 9, 1750) and the 
 town form of government resumed. 
 
 These constitute the entire number of municipal charters 
 granted during the colonial period. It will be noticed that 
 with the omission of the paper boroughs, all of the corpora- 
 tions were established in the five central colonies, New York, 
 New Jersey, Pennsylvania, Maryland, and Virginia. More- 
 over, most of the boroughs were within the limits of a com- 
 paratively small section. Nine of the fourteen active boroughs 
 lay in the stretch of country from Westchester, N.Y., 
 across New Jersey to Chester, Penn. a distance of one hun- 
 dred miles. Albany, N.Y., and Lancaster, Penn., were 
 not very far from the extremities of this area, leaving 
 only Williamsburg, Richmond, and Norfolk, in Virginia, and 
 Annapolis, in Maryland, as distinctly detached instances. 
 This concentration of boroughs within this limited area was 
 perhaps due to the influence of neighborhood example. It 
 is also significant that most of the boroughs were in those 
 colonies where the influence of the governors and the English 
 home government was strongest; while Winthrop's com- 
 ment on the incorporation of Agamenticus, the suppression 
 of the Maine charters by Massachusetts, and the absence 
 of incorporations in the New England colonies, indicate 
 a settled opposition there to the borough system. The town 
 meeting system gave a greater degree of local independence
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 59 
 
 than any form of charter issued during the colonial period, 
 and so long as no town had grown too large for this system 
 there was no special reason why charters of incorporation 
 should be sought in these colonies. 
 
 The period of borough formation in the American colonies 
 was during the sixty years from the incorporation of New 
 York (1686) to the charter of Trenton, N.J. (1746). * Why 
 it was that in spite of the continued growth of the country 
 no new charters were issued after 1746 is not altogether 
 clear; but, as the charters were grants from the governors 
 and not from the legislature, it is doubtless the case that the 
 growing opposition in the colonies to the mother country 
 and to the representatives of the English government had 
 its part in causing the movement to cease. 
 
 The advantages of incorporation were, however, recognized ; 
 and immediately after the Revolution there appeared a con- 
 siderable stream of municipal charters. Charleston, S.C., 
 was incorporated as a city in 1783; in 1784 Newport was 
 temporarily incorporated and Connecticut created five cities ; 2 
 in 1786 New Jersey after a rest of forty years renewed its 
 activity in this direction; in 1787 Baltimore was incor- 
 porated; and before the end of the century there were two 
 additional corporations in New York State. 3 By 1790 Boston 
 alone of the centres of population remained without having 
 adopted this method of government. 4 These new charters 
 
 1 The two Maine boroughs, chartered in 1641 and 1647, had no per- 
 manent existence, and were so completely unrelated to the later boroughs, 
 that they must be considered as sporadic cases and not as belonging to 
 any definite movement. 
 
 2 New Haven, Hartford, Middletown, New London, and Norwich. 
 
 3 Hudson and Schenectady. 
 
 4 Boston retained its town meeting until 1822, when it received a 
 city charter the first in Massachusetts. The Massachusetts towns 
 were in some respects corporate bodies from early colonial times (cf. 
 Hutchinson's Hist. Mass. Bay, pp.1, 175), and in 1694 they were expressly 
 authorized to sue and be sued. In 1785 they were formally incorporated. 
 The town meeting is, however, essentially a rural organization, not 
 adapted to urban conditions.
 
 60 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 were issued by the state legislatures instead of by the govern- 
 ors, and the democratic tendency was shown in the absence 
 of any close corporations. In all other respects, however, 
 these state charters were based closely on the charters and 
 government of the colonial boroughs, and thus form the 
 connecting link from the colonial institutions to the nine- 
 teenth century American city. 
 
 STATUS OF CITIZENS 
 
 The fundamental character of the borough governments, 
 as of all government, is determined by the relation of the 
 people to the governmental organization. This subject falls 
 into three subdivisions. The existence in the colonial 
 boroughs, as in the English boroughs, of a class of freemen 
 makes necessary some discussion of their special privileges. 
 Following this, the questions of the franchise, and the nature 
 of election methods, are considered. 
 
 The Freemen. The Dongan charter gave to the mayor, 
 recorder, and aldermen of New York the privilege of making 
 free citizens under their common seal, and the Montgomerie 
 charter reaffirmed this provision. In the Philadelphia char- 
 ter, the power of admitting freemen was vested in the whole 
 governing body. The other borough charters had similar 
 provisions for bestowing the freedom of the corporation on 
 residents. As a condition precedent to securing the freedom 
 of the city in New York, persons must be natural-born sub- 
 jects of the King of Great Britain, or else have been natural- 
 ized by act of the assembly or by letters of denization from 
 the lieutenant-governor. 
 
 The Albany and Elizabeth charters contained a similar 
 provision, but in Philadelphia any free denizen of the prov- 
 ince, twenty-one years of age, a resident of the city, pos- 
 sessing a freehold estate therein, or a resident for two years 
 having personal property to the value of fifty pounds, could be 
 admitted. Women as well as men were eligible for admission
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 61 
 
 to the freedom of the city. The fee which could be charged 
 for admission was in most cases limited by the charter. Thus 
 in New York and Elizabeth, N.J., the maximum fee was five 
 pounds; in Albany a merchant trader could be required to 
 pay three pounds twelve shillings, but a craftsman only half 
 that amount. In practice the Albany council fixed the fee 
 for natives of Albany at the nominal sum of two shillings. 
 In Philadelphia, there was no legal limitation on the amount 
 of the fee, and in practice it varied considerably. The 
 records show one case in which over three pounds was paid 
 and another where the fee was but a little over one pound. 
 
 None but freemen of the borough could practice any "art, 
 trade, mystery, or occupation" within the borough, except 
 during the great fairs. In Norfolk, Va., the freemen had an 
 advantage even during the fairs, as they were exempt from 
 one-half the tolls charged at such times. The monopoly of 
 trade must have been a privilege of some importance in the 
 early days. Albany had a monopoly of all trading with 
 the Indians to the north and west of the city, which must 
 have been an important advantage to the freemen of that 
 place. New York had a monopoly of bolting flour from 
 1684 to the passage, in Governor Fletcher's administration, 
 of the Bolting Act, which gave liberty to any one in the prov- 
 ince to bolt flour. In the later years of the colonial period 
 these special privileges of freemen were of but slight pecu- 
 niary value, and they do not seem ever to have had the im- 
 portance which they had in England. Perhaps one reason 
 for this was the readiness with which the corporations be- 
 stowed the freedom on those who were actually residents 
 of the borough. The nominal fee which the Albany council 
 charged indicates their willingness to extend the privilege 
 as far as possible. The New York corporation admitted 
 810 freemen between 1683 and 1740. 1 The number still 
 living in 1740 must have been materially less than 810, and 
 as the population of New York at this time was approaching 
 
 1 Memorial History of New York, I, 204.
 
 62 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 i.2,000, 1 it is evident that here at least all the householders 
 were not freemen; but the restriction of this privilege was 
 nowhere so strict or subject to such abuses as in England. 
 
 Except in those boroughs where the government was a close 
 corporation, all freemen were voters at the municipal elections, 
 and in boroughs which chose representatives to the colonial 
 legislature, all freemen (except in Philadelphia) were like- 
 wise electors at the elections for members of the legislature. 
 But these privileges were not usually confined to freemen, and 
 can thus be more thoroughly considered in the next 
 section. 
 
 The Suffrage. Considering the methods of borough gov- 
 ernment in England two centuries ago, it is a matter for 
 surprise that so few of the boroughs established on this side 
 of the Atlantic were made close corporations. In Philadelphia, 
 Annapolis, and Norfolk, the borough officials were chosen by 
 cooptation; that is, vacancies in the governing board were 
 filled by the remaining members. But in all the other 
 colonial boroughs there was a participation of the people in 
 the choice of the local officers. The records show no reason 
 for this difference in the charters granted to English boroughs 
 and those granted to the new settlements in America, and it 
 is especially difficult to understand why a popular election 
 should have been allowed in New York and Albany by the 
 Dongan charters, when it is remembered that these charters 
 were issued just after the attack on the London charter in 
 .1683, and after Jeffrey's circuit of England in which he made 
 the borough charters "fall down like the walls of Jericho." 
 Of course the American boroughs had no representation in 
 the English Parliament, and the interest of the Crown to 
 control Parliament was not brought into play. The lack of 
 this inducement may have been sufficient to cause the differ- 
 ent policy in the American borough charters. 
 
 Except in the close corporations, the municipal suffrage 
 extended to all the freemen and also to freeholders. The 
 
 1 Population 1737, 10,664, Documentary History of New York, I, 370.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 63 
 
 Dongan charter to New York had stated, rather vaguely, 
 that the aldermen, assistants, and constables should be 
 chosen by the "majority of voices of the inhabitants of each 
 ward"; but in the Montgomerie charter, the suffrage was 
 more clearly defined as belonging to " the freemen of the city, 
 being inhabitants and freeholders of each respective ward." 
 In 1771, the assembly of the province passed an act con- 
 ferring the franchise on 40 freeholders as well as on the 
 freemen. 1 The freeholder must have been in possession of 
 his freehold for at least one month before election day; and 
 the freemen must have held their freedom for at least three 
 months, and have actually resided in the ward one month 
 before election day. This same statute laid down the prin- 
 ciple of "one man, one vote" for New York municipal elec- 
 tions. Before its passage, freeholders owning property on 
 the East side of Broadway which lay partly in the West 
 ward and partly in the North ward had been accustomed 
 to vote in both wards. Under the act of 1771 they could 
 vote only in the West ward. 
 
 The Albany charter of 1686 was as vague as the New York 
 charter of the same year, in defining the qualifications for 
 municipal elections, and they do not seem to have been 
 clearly defined until 1773. In that year as a result of a con- 
 tested aldermanic election, the common council adopted 
 certain principles, 2 founded, it was said, on existing customs. 
 These regulations show the existence of a very extended 
 suffrage. The general rule was that "every person of the 
 age of twenty-one years, born under the British Dominions 
 and who has resided above six weeks in the city of Albany, 
 has a right to vote in the ward where he resides." In the 
 following year an ordinance was passed regulating elections, 
 which provided that not only natural-born subjects of the 
 Crown of Great Britain, but also subjects by an act of deni- 
 zation who had resided in the city at least forty days and 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 1492. 
 
 2 J. Munsell, Collections on the History of Albany, I, 254.
 
 64 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 had obtained the freedom of the city were entitled to vote, 1 
 and that all freeholders had a vote. No person under twenty- 
 one years of age, no alien, no servant or apprentice during 
 the time of servitude, and no prisoner or debtor in jail could 
 have a legal vote ; the votes of persons who were influenced by 
 bribes were declared null and void. The readiness of the 
 Albany council to admit freemen, and the admission of all free- 
 holders without regard to the value of their property, must have 
 made a more popular electorate in Albany than in New York. 
 
 The charters of the New Jersey boroughs provide that the 
 "freeholders and freemen" should elect the aldermen and 
 councilmen, while the two West Jersey charters also make 
 special mention of householders as electors. 2 Lancaster is 
 the only one of the Pennsylvania boroughs whose charter 
 clearly expressed the qualifications of an elector. The suf- 
 frage was by it conferred on inhabitants, householders within 
 the borough, who had resided there for a year preceding the 
 date of the election, and who had hired a house and ground 
 of the yearly value of five pounds sterling. 3 
 
 From the variety in the suffrage qualifications shown by 
 these special cases, it is evident that no definite statement 
 can be made giving a universal rule for the franchise in the 
 colonial boroughs. In general, it may be said that most of 
 the boroughs had popular elections, that the electorate in- 
 cluded a large proportion of the residents, and everywhere 
 all of the well-to-do classes, but that universal manhood 
 suffrage was as yet non-existent. 
 
 The close corporations continued until the Revolution. 
 The government under the Philadelphia charter ceased on 
 the capture of the city by the British, and it was not until 
 1789 that a new charter was granted by the state legislature, 
 and this provided for a popular election of the municipal 
 
 1 Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 266. 
 
 1 A. Scott in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., 2d series, IX, 158. Charter of 
 Elizabeth, in N. Murray, Notes on Elizabeth. 
 
 3 C. F. Bishop, History of Elections in the American Colonies, p. 225.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 65 
 
 officers. The Norfolk corporation continued as a self-elected 
 body until in 1787 the Virginia legislature passed an act * 
 providing for the election of the borough officers by the free- 
 holders and inhabitants of the borough qualified to vote for 
 burgesses to the assembly. The preamble to this act sets 
 forth that "the former method of electing common council- 
 men for the borough of Norfolk as fixed by the charter is 
 judged impolitic and unconstitutional." 
 
 The privilege of special representation of the boroughs in 
 the colonial legislatures was strictly analogous to the rep- 
 resentation of the English boroughs in Parliament. Phil- 
 adelphia, Annapolis, Williamsburg, Norfolk, Burlington, 
 Perth Amboy, and Elizabeth had such special representation ; 
 but the other boroughs were represented only as they formed 
 a part of the county or other electoral districts. The suf- 
 frage for the election of representatives to the assemblies had, 
 however, none of the abuses of the borough franchise in 
 England. Those boroughs which had a popular election 
 for local officers had practically the same suffrage for the 
 general colonial elections. Even in the close corporations, 
 the suffrage for the election of representatives was on a 
 popular basis. In Philadelphia, the citizens of the town 
 voted both for representatives of the city and for the county 
 members to the provincial assembly. 2 In Annapolis, the 
 corporation, and all persons inhabiting the city having an 
 estate of 20 sterling, were entitled to vote at the election 
 of two delegates to the colonial assembly. 3 The Norfolk 
 representative in the Virginia House of Burgesses was elected 
 by the members of the corporation, all the freeholders of the 
 borough owning half a lot of land with a house, all residents 
 with a visible estate worth 50, and all residents having 
 served five years to any trade within the borough. 4 
 
 1 Ch. 72. Hening, Statutes of Virginia, XII, 609. 
 
 2 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 47. 
 
 3 " Charter," in E. S. Riley, The Ancient City. 
 
 * " Charter," in Edward Ingle, Virginia Local Institutions, Johns Hop- 
 kins University Studies, III.
 
 66 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Elections. The annual municipal elections in New York 
 and Albany were fixed by the charter to occur on the feast 
 of St. Michael the Archangel, September 29. Each ward 
 constituted an election district, the aldermen acted as election 
 officers, and a plurality of votes elected. Voting seems to 
 have been viva voce, and there is one instance recorded of 
 voting by proxy. At the New York City election in 1689, 
 Captain Leysler appeared at the polls, and on the vote 
 for alderman, said: "I vote for my son Walters, my son 
 Jacob votes for his brother Walters, and my son Wal- 
 ters votes for himself; that's three, put them down." * 
 This voting by proxy seems, however, to have been an 
 irregular proceeding, not sanctioned by the customs of the 
 times. 
 
 The records of the Albany Council mention a special elec- 
 tion in 1706, at which the polls were to be open at 3 P.M.; 
 and a year later, at another special election, they were to be 
 open from one o'clock until sunset. 2 From the evidence 
 submitted at the trial of a contested election case in 1773, 
 we learn that by that time the polls were open from nine 
 o'clock in the morning until between four and five o'clock in 
 the afternoon, 3 and the council held that the returning officers 
 could not be compelled to record a vote after the closing of 
 the polls at five o'clock. The testimony of several witnesses 
 showed the prevalence of bribery at this election. From 
 five to ten pounds was said to have been the usual price for 
 a vote, but in two cases it appeared that forty pounds were 
 paid. 4 An interesting detail of Albany elections at variance 
 with the present American custom is shown by a resolution 
 of the common council in 1740. This declared that persons 
 whose trade or occupation was in one ward, and their residence 
 
 1 " A Modest and Impartial Narrative of Grievances," in Documents 
 relating to the Colonial History of New York, III, 674. 
 
 2 " City Records," in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, V, 143, 176. 
 8 C. F. Bishop, Colonial Elections, p. 233. 
 4 Ibid., p. 234.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 67 
 
 in another, should vote and be eligible for election from the 
 ward where their trade or occupation was located. 1 
 
 The New York statute of 1771, 2 already referred to as 
 regulating the suffrage, also laid down certain rules for the 
 conduct of the municipal elections in New York City. The 
 corporation was authorized to appoint returning officers for 
 each ward, and to fix the polling places. Every elector was 
 required to declare publicly whether he voted by virtue of 
 his freedom or his freehold. 
 
 The statutes contain no specific provisions concerning the 
 manner of conducting elections in the other boroughs. The 
 charter usually named the day on which officers should be 
 chosen, but otherwise the election machinery was fixed by 
 each corporation for itself. 
 
 ORGANIZATION 
 
 The grant of a borough charter in all cases provided for the 
 creation of a governing body, which should have the rights 
 and privileges of a corporation. The rights inhering in all 
 corporations were in most of the charters specifically men- 
 tioned. These were: (1) perpetual succession; (2) to be 
 persons in law capable of receiving, holding, and disposing 
 of lands, rents, chattels, etc. ; (3) to be qualified to sue and 
 to be subject to suit in the courts, and (4) to have a common 
 seal. The grant of these corporate powers was of course 
 the regular provision of the English charters, and was neces- 
 sary to give the government a legal status. 
 
 The regular form of organization provided for the colonial, 
 as for the English, boroughs, was that of a mayor, a recorder, 
 a small number of aldermen, and an equal or larger number 
 of councilmen or assistants; and the official title of the cor- 
 poration was generally, "The Mayor, Alderman, and Com- 
 monalty of ." The four small Pennsylvania boroughs 
 
 had a different and simpler organization : there were in each, 
 
 1 " City Records," November, 1740, in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, X, 
 93. 
 
 J Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 1492.
 
 68 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 two burgesses (one of whom was called the chief burgess), 
 and from four to six assistants. The borough officers of Tren- 
 ton, during the three years of the existence of the corporation, 
 were a chief burgess, a recorder, and several burgesses. 1 
 
 The Mayor. In the small boroughs the chief burgess was 
 chosen by popular vote, but in no case was a mayor regularly 
 selected in this way. In the close corporations he was elected 
 from the existing aldermen by the corporation; and in Eliza- 
 beth he was chosen by the mayor, aldermen, and common 
 councilmen. In the other boroughs where the aldermen 
 and councilmen were elected by the inhabitants, the mayor 
 was regularly appointed by the governor of the province. 
 During the Leysler troubles in the province of New York, 
 mayors were elected in the city of New York (in 1688 and 
 1689) and in the city of Albany (in 1689); but the former 
 method of appointment was restored in 1690. In New York 
 and Albany a former alderman was frequently appointed. 
 
 The term of office of the mayor was in all the boroughs one 
 year; 2 but in practice reappointments were frequent. The 
 later mayors of New York and Albany generally held the 
 position continuously for ten years. The mayor presided at 
 all meetings of the aldermen and of the common council, no 
 meeting being legal without his presence. But he had no 
 veto power over the acts of the council, and in Philadelphia 
 he did not even have a vote in the council. 3 He also had 
 charge of the execution of the laws and ordinances of the 
 council. The Elizabeth charter provides that the mayor 
 shall have charge of the borough " in as full and ample manner 
 as is usual and customary for other mayors to have in like 
 corporations in our realm of England." 4 
 
 1 A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 154. 
 
 2 Howe, Collections on Virginia (p. 394), states that Samuel Boush 
 was chosen mayor of Norfolk "until a vacancy occurred by his death 
 or resignation"; but the charter of Norfolk provided for an annual 
 election on St. John the Baptist's Day. 
 
 3 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 11. 
 
 4 " Charter," in Murray, Notes on Elizabeth, p. 36.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 69 
 
 In New York and Albany the mayor, by the charters, had 
 full control over the licensing of tavern keepers, and sellers 
 of wine, cider, etc. A law of the New York provincial as- 
 sembly, passed in 1713, 1 named the mayor and aldermen 
 conjointly as the licensing authority. Previous action had 
 asserted the power of the legislature to supplement the 
 charters; but this statute, in direct violation of the charters, 
 does not seem to have been enforced. The Montgomerie 
 charter of New York reasserted the authority of the mayor 
 as the grantor of licenses. In Albany the non-compliance 
 with the statute is shown distinctly by the records of a long 
 and interesting dispute between an ex-mayor and the council 
 over the question whether the license fees were a perquisite 
 of the mayor's office or should go to the city treasury. As 
 the ex-mayor had possession of the funds, the council in the 
 end agreed to compromise the matter by a payment into the 
 city treasury of about one-third the amount of the fees. 2 
 
 The mayor frequently held, ex-officio, minor offices in the 
 boroughs. In New York and Albany he was clerk of the 
 market ; in Albany he was also to act as coroner, and in New 
 York as water bailiff. In Philadelphia he acted as treasurer 
 and as inspector of bread bakeries. 3 While the mayor had 
 no power of appointment, these combinations of several 
 offices in his own person served to centre the administration 
 to a considerable degree in his hands. His influence in the 
 management of municipal matters was further increased by 
 the fact that he was usually a man of considerable experience 
 in the affairs of the corporation and that in practice he held 
 office a considerable number of years. 
 
 The Recorder was the member of the borough government 
 supposed to know most about legal matters. But only in 
 Norfolk was he required to be a person "learned in law"; 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 263, Oct. 23, 1713. 
 3 City Records, in J. Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 142 ff. 
 3 " Wharton School of Political Science," City Government of Philadel- 
 phia, p. 17.
 
 70 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and there he was allowed to appoint a deputy, for whom the 
 qualification does not seem to have been necessary. In 
 fact, during the colonial period, the recorder of Norfolk was 
 invariably a non-resident. The Albany charter required 
 the recorder (and also the town clerk) " to be a person of good 
 capacity and understanding," a qualification not demanded 
 in the case of mayor, aldermen, or assistants. 
 
 The recorder was chosen in the same way as the mayor; 
 in the close corporations by the corporation, and in the 
 other boroughs by appointment of the governors. 1 In 
 Trenton, however, he was chosen by the common council. 2 
 The presence of the recorder was required to make a quorum 
 of the borough court. His distinctive functions in colonial 
 times are nowhere clearly indicated. Probably his main 
 duties were drafting of papers in legal form and advising the 
 mayor and aldermen in the discharge of their judicial functions. 
 
 The Aldermen. The number of aldermen was every- 
 where quite small. In New York there were at first but five, 
 but after 1679 there were six, and the Montgomerie charter 
 (1730) increased this to seven. Philadelphia had six alder- 
 men under the charter of 1691, but the charter of 1701 pro- 
 vided for eight aldermen. Albany, Annapolis, and Williams- 
 burg had each six aldermen; Norfolk had eight; while 
 strangely enough the largest number was provided for the 
 ephemeral borough of Agamenticus, which, when created 
 a city, was empowered to elect twelve aldermen. 3 
 
 In the close corporations the aldermen were chosen by the 
 corporation, and in Norfolk only councilmen were eligible. 
 In Perth Amboy they were chosen by the common council, 
 as were the burgesses in Trenton. In the other boroughs 
 they were elected by popular vote under the same franchise 
 as for the election of common councilmen. New York and 
 
 1 This was the case also in Elizabeth, where, as has been seen, the mayor 
 was chosen by the common council. 
 
 8 A. Scott, N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 155. 
 
 8 "Charter," in Hazard, Historical Collections, p. 470.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 71 
 
 Albany alone seem to have elected by districts ; in the former, 
 there was one alderman for each ward, and in the latter, 
 two aldermen for each of the three wards. In the close 
 corporations, and also in Trenton, the term of office for alder- 
 men was for life; elsewhere, except in Elizabeth, a one-year 
 tenure prevailed; in Elizabeth, N.J., the term was three 
 years. 
 
 The aldermen in conjunction with the mayor, recorder, and 
 assistants or councilmen formed the common council, which 
 sat as one body. Aldermen, however, had additional powers, 
 as justices of the peace, members of the borough court, and 
 in some cases members of the county court. In Philadelphia, 
 the mayor and aldermen had most of the appointing power; 
 and in Norfolk after 1752 they were the licensing authority 
 for the borough. 1 
 
 The Councilmen. The number of councilmen was gener- 
 ally larger than the number of aldermen, but New York and 
 Albany had the same number of each class. Annapolis had 
 ten councilmen, Philadelphia had twelve; while Williams- 
 burg, Norfolk, and Agamenticus, in accordance with the old 
 English custom, had twice the number of aldermen in the 
 second class, giving them respectively twelve, sixteen, and 
 twenty-four councilmen. 
 
 The councilmen were chosen in the close corporations, not 
 by the whole corporation, but by the mayor, recorder, and 
 aldermen, who were limited to the inhabitants of the borough. 
 The Norfolk charter required councilmen to be freeholders; 
 but a statute of the Virginia assembly passed in 1752 declared 
 twelve months' residence a sufficient qualification. 2 Except 
 in the close corporations, the councilmen, or assistants, were 
 chosen by popular election under the franchise already 
 described. The tenure was, as for aldermen, generally a 
 single year; but in Elizabeth three years, and in Trenton 
 and also in the close corporations for life. The Philadelphia 
 
 1 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, VI, 263.
 
 72 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 charter of 1691 had provided for annual election of council- 
 men, but life tenure was introduced by the charter of 1701. 
 In Perth Amboy the assistants were not chosen until it was 
 known who were to be the aldermen for the next year, 1 thus 
 making it possible for defeated candidates for aldermen to be 
 afterward elected as councilmen. 
 
 In none of the colonial boroughs were the councilmen a 
 distinct body. They were members of the common council, 
 as were also the mayor, recorder, and aldermen; but the 
 councilmen alone could not form a meeting of the common 
 council the presence of a certain number of aldermen with 
 the mayor was necessary for a quorum. The special functions 
 and title of the aldermen made the separation of the govern- 
 ing authorities into two bodies an easy transition, but through- 
 out the colonial period there was no bicameral system in 
 municipal government. 
 
 Other Charter Officials. Besides the members of the cor- 
 porations, the charters of the various colonial boroughs 
 provided for a few of the more important administrative 
 officers. There was always a town clerk, usually appointed 
 by royal commission through the governors of the provinces. 
 The Elizabeth charter, however, in this as in other respects, 
 gave larger powers to the residents of the borough, who 
 chose their own town clerk. The tenure of office for the town 
 clerk was not determined by the charters, and the position 
 seems to have been generally regarded as a permanent post. 
 The Albany charter required the lieutenant-governor to 
 appoint a person of "good capacity and understanding," 
 the only instance in which any qualifications are laid down 
 for the office. The town clerk kept the official records of 
 the corporation, and also acted as clerk of the borough court. 
 In Burlington, N.J., the county clerk of the peace was au- 
 thorized to act as clerk for the city. 2 
 
 Another official whom all of the boroughs must have found 
 
 1 W. A. Whitehead, Early History of Perth Amboy (1856), p. 52. 
 7 A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 155.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 73 
 
 necessary, but who is mentioned in but three of the charters, 
 is the treasurer, or chamberlain, as he is sometimes styled. 
 In New York and Albany, this officer was chosen annually 
 by the common council ; and in Philadelphia the mayor per- 
 formed the duties of the office. Elsewhere the office was 
 left to be created and regulated by each corporation for itself. 
 
 A few of the more important boroughs in England had 
 been constituted as counties with a separate sheriff, and thus 
 entirely separated from the jurisdiction of the sheriff of the 
 shire in which they were geographically located. In this 
 country, New York and Albany were the only boroughs 
 which had this distinctive feature. The Philadelphia charter 
 provided that the sheriff of the county should act as sheriff 
 of the city, but elsewhere there is no mention of the office. 
 
 Fines for Refusal to accept Office. An interesting feature in 
 some of the borough charters is the imposition of penalties 
 for refusal to accept office. Such fines were authorized by 
 the charters of New York, Philadelphia, Albany, Burlington, 
 and Trenton, and for some offices by the charters of the East 
 Jersey boroughs. 1 The amount of the fines varied consider- 
 ably; the highest authorized was in the Albany charter for 
 refusing to accept the position of mayor, in which case a fine 
 of twenty pounds could be imposed. Five and ten pounds 
 were the most usual sums, and in Philadelphia a refusal to 
 act as councilman could be met with a fine of not over four 
 pounds. 
 
 In Philadelphia fines were often paid in preference to serv- 
 ing. 2 The Albany city records show but one case in that 
 borough, when in 1703 Abram Cuyler was fined five pounds 
 for refusing to serve as assistant. The following day, on 
 petition of Mr. Cuyler, the fine was reduced to three pounds, 
 and this he agreed to pay. 3 
 
 Overseers of the Poor and Constables. See A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. 
 Soc. Proc., IX, 158; W. A. Whitehead, Early History of Perth Amboy, p. 52. 
 
 2 " Wharton School of Political Science," City Government of Philadel- 
 phia, p. 17. 
 
 8 City Records, in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, IV, 244.
 
 74 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Wards. The division of some of the boroughs into wards 
 for election and administrative purposes was, like other 
 features of the charters, a transfer of English methods. 
 New York and Albany were divided into wards by their 
 first charters, the former into seven wards, the latter into 
 three. Philadelphia was not marked off into wards until 
 1704. 1 The second charter of Perth Amboy (1753) ap- 
 parently divided Perth from South Amboy, thus making 
 two wards in the city ; and the second charter of New Bruns- 
 wick divided that city into two wards. 2 The Elizabeth 
 charter does not establish any ward lines directly, but au- 
 thorizes the mayor, aldermen, and common council to divide 
 the borough into wards. 3 
 
 In view of the more or less frequency with which ward lines 
 are changed in modern American cities, it is worth noticing 
 that the lines established by the New York and Albany char- 
 ters remained unchanged throughout the colonial period, 
 although during the ninety years from the charters to the 
 Revolution the population of New York had increased from 
 less than 4000 to over 20,000 and Albany had grown from 
 little more than a hamlet to a town of 3500 inhabitants. 
 
 Town Meetings. No discussion of the governmental 
 organization of the New Jersey boroughs would be complete 
 without taking note of the continued existence alongside the 
 borough government of the town meeting. The town system 
 had been transplanted from New England to New Jersey, 
 and had taken root before the creation of the boroughs; 
 and in fact all of the New Jersey boroughs had boundaries 
 coterminous with those of the townships. 4 In Elizabeth, 
 the town meeting continued to act after the creation of the 
 borough as if there were no organized government. The 
 entries in the Town Book from 1720 to 1788 show that the 
 
 1 Allinsnn and Penrose, Philadelphia, 37. 
 
 2 A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 170. 
 1 See " Charter," in Murray, Notes, p. 43. 
 
 4 A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 169.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPOEATIONS IN THE COLONIES 75 
 
 town meeting voted the levy of taxes, and town officers 
 collected them. 1 The Burlington Town Book records town 
 meetings from 1693 through the next century. The city 
 charter itself was the work of the town meeting, and after 
 the new government went into operation the town meetings, 
 even the annual March meeting for the election of officers, 
 were held. The town meeting appears to have confined its 
 jurisdiction in most cases to the original town property and 
 to the voting of taxes; while the city officers fulfilled the 
 special functions and powers conferred by the charter. 2 
 Even in New Brunswick, where the town organization was 
 but six years old when the charter was issued, the town 
 meeting was not wholly supplanted; and as late as 1793 the 
 city authorities passed an ordinance providing for the assess- 
 ment and collection of a tax levied at a town meeting pre- 
 viously held. 3 
 
 In the charters of the small Pennsylvania boroughs, there 
 were provisions for assembling town meetings for the passage 
 of by-laws and ordinances. If, however, we may judge from 
 the example of Bristol, the town meeting was usually nothing 
 but the meeting of the town council and borough officers. 
 Popular assemblies were called only occasionally when an 
 important tax was to be laid or a charter amended. 4 
 
 JUDICIAL AND LEGISLATIVE FUNCTIONS 
 
 Judicial. The colonial borough like its English proto- 
 type was more of a judicial than an administrative organiza- 
 tion. Those functions of municipal government which are 
 preeminent to-day the construction and management of 
 public works, and the control and direction of large forces 
 of administrative employees had not yet developed to 
 any large extent; and one finds that in the borough govern- 
 ment the judicial functions were the prominent features. 
 
 1 A Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 166. 2 Ibid., pp. 168, 170. 
 8 Ibid., p. 167. 4 W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, p. 36.
 
 76 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The judicial powers of the boroughs were vested in the 
 mayor, recorder, and aldermen. Each of these, in the first 
 place, was during the term of his office a justice of the peace; 
 and as such had jurisdiction over petty civil suits (not in- 
 volving over forty shillings), and could hear and commit 
 persons charged with criminal offences. In addition to this, 
 the mayor, recorder, and aldermen of each borough, sitting 
 together, formed a local court which held stated sessions for 
 the trial of civil and criminal cases. These courts went 
 under different names, and their jurisdiction was not in all 
 cases coextensive, but in general they resembled each other. 
 
 The mayor's court of New York met once a fortnight before 
 the charter of 1730 ; * after that on Tuesday of each week. 
 The Albany court met once a fortnight. The Williamsburg 
 and Norfolk courts of Hustings 2 and the Amboy city court s 
 held a term once a month. The Elizabeth court of record 
 held four sessions a year, on the first Tuesday in March, 
 June, September, and December. In all cases the presence 
 of the mayor, recorder, and a specified number (usually about 
 one-half) of the aldermen was necessary to a quorum. 
 
 The jurisdiction of the New York and Albany courts in- 
 cluded all civil causes, real, personal, or mixed; and their de- 
 cision was final in all cases involving not over twenty pounds. 
 The New York court could also try cases of petty larceny, 
 riots, trespass, and such like. The Philadelphia court had full 
 jurisdiction over all felonies and misdemeanors, and also 
 had authority to cause the removal of nuisances and en- 
 croachments on the streets. 4 The Williamsburg and Nor- 
 folk courts of Hustings had jurisdiction over all actions 
 personal and mixed, involving not over twenty pounds. 
 This limitation was, however, removed from the Williamsburg 
 
 1 " Dongan's Report to the Committee of Trade" (1687), in Documen- 
 tary History of New York, I, 96. 
 
 " Norfolk Charter," Hening's Statutes of Virginia, IV, 130. 
 8 W. A. Whitehead, Early History of Perth Amboy, p. 52. 
 4 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, pp. 14, 49.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 77 
 
 court in 1736, 1 and from the Norfolk court in 1765 ; 2 and 
 the jurisdiction of these courts was thus made equal to that 
 of the county courts. 
 
 Besides their duties in the borough courts, the mayor, re- 
 corder, and aldermen were usually members of the county 
 courts of quarter-sessions; and in New York and Elizabeth 
 they comprised the whole membership of the county courts. 
 In Philadelphia only the mayor and recorder were admitted 
 to the county courts. In the Albany county court one of 
 the city members of the court was presiding officer. The 
 jurisdiction of these courts was similar to those of the courts 
 of quarter-sessions in England, and is set forth at length in 
 the charter to Elizabeth. 3 
 
 Legislative. The charters uniformly gave to the common 
 council of each borough, authority to make, ordain, and 
 establish such laws and ordinances as should "seem to be 
 good, useful, or necessary for the good rule and government 
 of the body corporate," 4 and to alter and repeal the same. 
 But such ordinances or by-laws must not be repugnant to the 
 king's prerogative, the laws of England, or the laws of the 
 general assembly of the colony; while further restrictions 
 were added in many of the charters. 
 
 Thus, in New York and Albany the ordinances expired at the 
 end of a year, unless they had been confirmed by the lieu- 
 tenant-governor and council. The Dongan charter to New 
 York City had set the limit at three months. In Perth 
 Amboy and New Brunswick the ordinances of the common 
 councils were binding for only six months, unless within six 
 weeks after their passage they were approved by the governor 
 and council. 5 The practical effect of these provisions was to 
 compel the councils to go through the form of reenacting 
 the body of ordinances every year or six months, as the case 
 
 1 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, IV, 542. 
 
 *Ibid., VIII, 153. 
 
 3 In N. Murray, Notes on Elizabeth, p. 38. 
 
 * New York Charter of 1730. 
 
 6 A. Scott, in N. J. Hist. Soc. Proc., IX, 156.
 
 78 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 might be. This seems to have answered all purposes, and 
 there are no indications of any attempt being made to secure 
 the approval of the higher authorities. The later New 
 Jersey charters seem to have been based on the principle 
 that the common councils could be trusted, for this restrictive 
 clause is omitted, thus relieving them of the necessity of 
 periodically reenacting the body of local by-laws. 
 
 The character of the ordinances passed in the various 
 boroughs was much the same. In all, the most pressing 
 question seems to have been to prevent cattle and other 
 animals from roaming at large on the streets. Regulating 
 the cleaning of the streets, and later, their pavement, is 
 another important subject. Ordinances providing for the 
 observation of the Lord's Day, prohibiting fast driving, 
 regulating the prices of bread and meat, regulations for 
 avoiding danger from fire, rules for the public markets, and 
 for preventing tumultuous gatherings of negroes and slaves, 
 are found in most of the boroughs. 
 
 At the same time, the special conditions of individual 
 boroughs led to the passage of many ordinances peculiar to 
 each. Thus in Albany the defence of the city against Indian 
 attacks and the regulation of the Indian trade were constant 
 subjects of municipal legislation; and in Philadelphia an 
 ordinance to prevent actors from performing plays l was duly 
 enacted. 
 
 In regard to the regulation of the prices of food, some of the 
 assizes established by the Albany council may be of interest. 
 On December 7, 1706, it was resolved by the common council, 
 
 "that ye following assisse be made of bread, Vizt. that one pound neet 
 "weight of fine flower Bread shall be sold for Six stuyvens or l^d. and 
 "eight and a half pound like weight bread Bake as ye meel comes from 
 "ye mill for 9d. and Eight pound like weight Bread made of ye course 
 "flowr for 9d. or four pound for four pence half penny." 2 
 
 The penalty for a violation of this ordinance was six shillings. 
 In 1757 the following prices of meat were established : 
 
 1 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 51. 
 
 2 " City Records," in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, V, 143.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 79 
 
 "Meat 4d. a pound. 
 Head and Pluck of Calf, one shilling a pound. 
 
 " of Sheep, 9d. a pound. 
 " " " of Lamb, 6d. a pound." 1 
 
 These prices were changed from time to time by ordinance; 
 and they seem to have in fact determined' the market price, 
 for in 1770 the butchers of the city presented a petition for an 
 alteration in prices, which, however, the council declined to 
 change. 2 
 
 BOROUGH ADMINISTRATION 
 
 In the colonial boroughs the administrative duties of the 
 municipal authorities did not so completely subordinate their 
 judicial and legislative powers as in the city of to-day. Never- 
 theless their administrative functions were considerable, espe- 
 cially in the management of markets, the repair and cleansing 
 of streets, and in some boroughs in maintaining municipal 
 wharves and ferries. Some branches of municipal activity, 
 as in the case of the distribution of poor relief, were generally 
 controlled by other officials than those connected with the 
 borough government. Others, such as the police and fire 
 departments, waterworks and sewerage systems, had not, 
 even by the end of the colonial period, reached the stage of 
 systematic organization; but the beginnings and early steps 
 in these lines are of no little interest. 
 
 It is worth noting that most of the administrative functions 
 were revenue producing undertakings such as would fall 
 within the controversial field of municipal ownership at the 
 present time, as markets, docks, wharves, and water supply. 
 And it is only in the latter part of the colonial period that 
 we find significant beginnings in those branches of municipal 
 administration such as police, fire protection, and street 
 improvements supported by taxation, which are the most 
 important and universal in our day. 
 
 Markets and Fairs. The common council of each borough 
 
 1 " City Records," in J. Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 108. 
 > Ibid., I, 217.
 
 80 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 was empowered by its charter to establish a market, to be 
 held on certain days of each week; and also to hold annual 
 or semiannual fairs. The number of market days in each 
 week varied from one to three, according to the needs of the 
 town. In Bristol, markets were held every Thursday ; * 
 in Albany and Philadelphia, twice a week (Wednesday and 
 Saturday) ; 2 in New York and Norfolk, three times a week 
 (Tuesday, Thursday, and Saturday). Market houses were 
 built by the corporation, generally in the centre of the streets ; 
 and the rentals of the stalls formed a substantial source of 
 revenue to the government. New York had two market- 
 houses before 1686, 3 and five more were built before the 
 Montgomerie charter was issued. 4 In Albany there were 
 three market-houses, one in each ward. 5 
 
 At the markets only freemen of the borough could sell 
 goods; but the fairs were open to all comers, though in 
 Norfolk the freemen of that borough were exempt from one- 
 half of the tolls. At these fairs, law and order were in a 
 measure suspended, and toward the end of the colonial 
 period there was on that account great opposition to them, 
 especially in Pennsylvania. On November 10, 1773, the 
 council of Bristol borough resolved that the fair was useless 
 on account of the large number of stores, and that "the de- 
 bauchery, idleness, and drunkenness, consequent on the 
 meeting of the lowest class of people together, is a real evil 
 and calls for redress." 6 In Philadelphia there was also a 
 demand for the suppression of the fairs as nuisances. 7 But 
 the borough councils could not abolish a chartered institu- 
 tion, and even the provincial assembly doubted its powers to 
 change the charters, and did not abolish fairs until 1796. 
 
 1 W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, p. 40. 
 
 2 " Albany Charter," Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia. 
 8 Preamble to Dongan's' Charter. 
 
 4 Kent, Charter of New York, p. 25. 
 
 " City Records," in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany. 
 
 * W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, p. 41. 
 7 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 49.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 81 
 
 Ferries. The New York City authorities had established 
 a ferry to Long Island before the corporation had been con- 
 firmed by Dongan's charter, 1 and the power to maintain this 
 was conferred by that charter. In 1708, on the petition of 
 the corporation a special charter was granted, 2 conferring 
 the exclusive privilege of maintaining the public ferry to 
 Long Island, and of establishing and maintaining such ad- 
 ditional ferries as they should think fit. This charter also 
 granted to the corporation of New York all the vacant land 
 between high- and low-water marks on Long Island from 
 Wallabout to Red Hook, to enable them to provide suitable 
 accommodation on that side of the river for the ferryboats. 
 For these privileges the corporation was to pay a yearly rent 
 of five shillings to the collector and receiver-general at New 
 York. The charter of 1730 confirmed these ferry rights to 
 the corporation, and two years later the provincial assembly 
 passed a law reaffirming the monopoly of ferries to Long 
 Island, and at the same time regulating rates of ferriage. 3 
 
 Albany also had municipal ferries, which like those of New 
 York were let out to private persons. The common council 
 established the rates of fare, and there is no record of any 
 interference by the provincial assembly with the manage- 
 ment of the Albany ferries. The corporation of Philadelphia 
 established ferries; but ferry privileges were also granted to 
 individuals by the provincial assemblies. As the number of 
 ferries increased in importance with the expansion of the 
 city, the control of them became a frequent source of con- 
 tention between the provincial government, the corporation, 
 and individuals; but the corporation never succeeded in 
 obtaining a monopoly grant of power over ferries. 4 
 
 Between Bristol, Penn., and Burlington, N.J., there was 
 a ferry which was a matter of frequent consideration by the 
 
 1 Preamble to Charter of 1686. 
 
 z J. Kent, Charter of the City of New York, p. 26. 
 
 3 Ch. 593, Colonial Laws of New York, October 14, 1732. 
 
 4 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 48.
 
 82 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Bristol authorities. As in Albany the council would lease 
 the ferry and fix the rate of tolls. When, however, the 
 time came for the ferryman to pay his rent he usually rep- 
 resented that his tolls were too light to pay the sum agreed 
 on, and the council was always merciful enough to let him 
 off with paying half. 1 
 
 Docks and Wharves. The New York, Albany, and Phila- 
 delphia corporations were authorized to build public docks 
 and wharves. The Montgomerie charter to New York 
 granted the corporation for this purpose the soil under the 
 waters of the Hudson and East rivers for four hundred feet 
 below low-water mark on Manhattan Island from Bestaver's 
 Kill on the Hudson River to Corlear's Hook on the East 
 River. Such docks and wharves were let out, in the same 
 fashion as the ferries, to private individuals, who collected 
 wharfage from vessels using the docks. The rental of the 
 New York docks was 30 in 1710, 73 in 1740, and 620 in 
 1766 figures which illustrate the development of New 
 York commerce as well as of the city dock system. 
 
 At Albany the wharves were, of course, much less important 
 than those at New York. Before 1766 they seem to have been 
 almost neglected by the city authorities; but in that year 
 three new docks were ordered to be built, another was deter- 
 mined on two years later, and in 1774 an addition to the 
 North dock was voted by the council. The rental of the 
 docks at Albany was determined by public auction, and in 
 the twenty years after 1766 varied from 55 to 103. 2 
 
 Streets and Roads. New York was the only borough 
 where the corporation had the power to lay out new streets 
 through private property, and even here their authority was 
 limited. In the Dongan charter it was expressly provided 
 that the consent of the owner must be obtained; but by 
 statute in 1691 3 the corporation was empowered to take 
 
 1 W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, pp. 38, 39. 
 
 2 " City Records," in Munsell, Collections on Albany, I. 
 
 3 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 18.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 83 
 
 possession under certain conditions, without the consent of 
 the owner. The law specifically asserted that no authority 
 was given "to break through any ground fenced or enclosed, 
 or to take away any person's house or habitation." The 
 city government could, however, use open and vacant land 
 on payment of damages as assessed by a jury. Even this 
 restricted authority in the matter of opening new streets 
 does not seem to have been within the scope of any other 
 borough corporation. 
 
 The borough governments had more power on the subject 
 of paving and cleaning the streets. As early as March 12, 
 1694-5, the Albany council required each householder "to 
 make or cause to be made eight feet ground before his own 
 house fronting on ye street paved with stones." l And again 
 on December 3, 1717, an ordinance was passed requiring 
 owners and tenants of houses fronting on the streets to "re- 
 pair and pave ye same each half y e breadth of y e s d streets." 2 
 Similar ordinances were passed from time to time. The paving 
 was of cobblestones, laid from the sides of the street out, leav- 
 ing the centre unpaved as an open watercourse or gutter. 
 
 The New York council required the property owners on the 
 principal streets to pave the streets in this manner. 3 In 
 Philadelphia many of the inhabitants about 1718 voluntarily 
 paved in front of their premises; and in 1736 an ordinance 
 was passed requiring this under penalty of having it done at 
 their expense by the corporation. 4 It is not, however, until 
 the very end of the colonial period that any systematic 
 attempts at paving were entered on. A Pennsylvania act 
 of 1762 provided for the election of six road commissioners, 
 who, in cooperation with the mayor, recorder, and aldermen, 
 should direct the management of the streets, could contract 
 for work and materials, and in cooperation with the assessors 
 
 1 " City Records," in J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, II, 136. 
 
 2 Ibid., VI, 73. 
 
 3 Memorial History of New York, II, 165. 
 
 4 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 30.
 
 84 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 could levy taxes for street purposes 1 . Two years later the 
 New York assembly passed an act 2 authorizing the corpora- 
 tion of New York City to appoint commissioners to regulate 
 and keep in repair the highways and other public roads, 
 and to raise by a general tax such sums as should be necessary. 
 In 1775 a special tax of 200 was authorized, for street 
 purposes. 3 Just how far action was taken under these 
 statutes is not clear; but in Philadelphia there does not seem 
 to have been any radical improvement, and "the streets 
 continued to be ill-managed even for those provincial days." 4 
 
 Keeping the streets free from rubbish and obstructions was 
 one of the important tasks of the borough authorities. The 
 usual method was to pass an ordinance requiring each house- 
 holder to keep clear the street in front of his premises, and in 
 some instances it was found necessary to pass a special ordi- 
 nance naming a particular street which was to be cleared. 
 
 Open drains were constructed to carry off surplus water 
 and refuse; and the New York corporation early constructed 
 what was called a "common sewer" through the great dock. 5 
 The only other indication of anything approaching a sewerage 
 system is that the Philadelphia road commissioners, pro- 
 vided for in the Act of 1768, were to have charge of the build- 
 ing and repair of drains and sewers. 6 Such sewers as were 
 constructed could only have been for the removal of surface 
 water and street refuse; and no complete sewerage system 
 for carrying of fcecal matter was constructed until after the 
 colonial period. 
 
 Water Supply. Throughout the colonial period the 
 water supply of the boroughs was from pumps and springs. 
 New York and Albany from the earliest records had munici- 
 
 1 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 32. 
 J Colonial Laws of New York,-ch. 1268, October 20, 1764. 
 s Ibid., ch. 1698. 
 
 4 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 34. 
 
 * In 1717 a special tax of 500 was authorized for extending the sewer 
 farther into the river. Colonial Laws, ch. 327. 
 8 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 31.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 85 
 
 pal pumps, the building and repair of which were frequent 
 subjects of discussion in the council meetings. By a statute 
 of 1753 * the common council of New York was required to 
 appoint overseers of wells and pumps, whose duty it was to 
 keep the public wells and pumps in good order. In Phila- 
 delphia the town pumps were originally erected and owned 
 by private persons, but their great importance led to various 
 ordinances for their regulation. Thus in 1713 the common 
 council ordered that before a pump should be driven the 
 location should be viewed by the mayor, recorder, and three 
 aldermen. This ordinance also authorized the owners of 
 pumps to charge rent for their use by neighbors. In 1756 
 the general control of pumps in Philadelphia was placed in 
 the hands of wardens, who were given power to sink new 
 wells, to purchase private pumps, and to assess such house- 
 holders as used the public pumps. 2 
 
 In 1774 the Albany council undertook the establishment of 
 what may be called a waterworks plant. A contract was 
 made for laying water-pipes from the springs to the pumps, 
 a distance of 766 feet, and for building cisterns at the springs. 
 We have here, though in a decidedly primitive style, the 
 prototypes of the three main elements in a system of water 
 supply, a reservoir, an aqueduct, and a pumping station. 
 
 Fire-engines. It was not until well into the eighteenth 
 century that any of the colonial boroughs had secured for 
 itself a fire-engine. Previous to that time the only method 
 of extinguishing fires was by means of buckets of water, and 
 in several boroughs householders were required to keep on 
 hand a specified number of leathern buckets to be used 
 whenever a fire should break out. In 1718 the corporation 
 of Philadelphia bought an engine for fifty pounds. 3 Twelve 
 years later the need of additional protection against fire was 
 felt, and three new engines were ordered, as well as 200 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 941, December 12, 1753. 
 
 2 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 37. 
 
 3 Ibid., p. 41.
 
 50 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 leather buckets, 20 ladders, and 25 hooks. In the same year 
 (1730) the city of New York was authorized to purchase 
 two fire-engines; 1 and in February, 1731-2, the Albany 
 council directed that an order be given for a "water engine 
 of Richard Newsham, engineer, of the fifth sort, with six- 
 foot sucking Pipe with a leathern Pipe of forty foot, includ- 
 ing brass screws." 2 In 1764 the Burlington council ordered 
 a fire-engine, which, like the others, had to be brought over 
 from England. 
 
 The possession of fire-engines necessitated certain expenses 
 for housing them and keeping them in repair; but other than 
 this there were no steps in the direction of establishing a paid 
 fire department. The New York volunteer fire companies 
 were first organized by a statute of 1737. 3 This provided for 
 a force of 42 men, who were exempt from military and jury 
 duty. The number of members was increased by subsequent 
 acts, until by 1773 it numbered 140. 4 
 
 Police. The systematic patrol of the streets in the inter- 
 est of peace and order is a feature of municipal government 
 that had not been thought of in the organization of the 
 colonial boroughs. As in England, each borough had its 
 high constable and under constables, but their duties were 
 confined to the execution of the orders of the court, and 
 there seems to have been nothing corresponding to our 
 modern police system. New York had a military watch 
 during the first French war, and again in 1741, during the 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 550 (1730). 
 
 2 " City Records," in Munsell, Annals of Albany, X, 19. 
 
 The Albany Council ordered a second fire-engine in 1740, and a third in 
 1762. The bill for this last presents some curious features. The Council 
 in making their order in March had specified that the engine should cost 
 fifty-five pounds ; but the bill as presented was as follows : 
 Cost of the Engine in London 68 13s. 8d. at 95% advance . 134-1-0 
 
 Freight from London to New York 19-4-0 
 
 Interest on note for 104-10 5-4-6 
 
 158-9-6 
 "City Records," in Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 141. 
 
 8 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 670 (1737). 
 
 4 Ibid., ch. 1198 (1762); ch. 1367 (1768); ch. 1579 (1773).
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 87 
 
 excitement connected with the Negro riots. 1 Albany, which 
 was exposed to Indian attacks, maintained a military night 
 watch at the stockade during the second French war (from 
 1699 to 1713), which was revived again from 1745-1748. 2 
 When the New York military watch was given up in 1697, it 
 was replaced by four bellmen, or watchmen, the forerunners of 
 the modern policeman. Their duties were to go through the 
 town at night ringing a bell to call the time and state of the 
 weather, and to inform the constable of any disorder or fires. 
 In 1700 the provincial council of Pennsylvania appointed 
 a watchman for Philadelphia, and in 1713 Albany established 
 the office of bellman. 3 
 
 In Philadelphia, beginning in 1704, an attempt was made to 
 establish a night watch, to be filled by the citizens in turn; 
 but it was found difficult to get each one to do his share, and 
 the watch seems to have been irregular and inefficient. In 
 New York when the military watch established in 1741 was 
 withdrawn, it was replaced by a force of twelve night watch- 
 men. 4 This continued only during 1742, and was followed 
 by the system of obligatory and unpaid citizen service. The 
 establishment of a considerable force of paid watchmen was 
 begun at Philadelphia in 1750; the charge of the force was, 
 however, not given to the corporation, but to six elected 
 wardens. 5 Eleven years later the New York corporation 
 was authorized to levy a tax of 1800 for providing street 
 lamps and paying night watchmen, 6 and a force of watch- 
 men was definitely established. In 1763 and 1764 the two 
 Virginia boroughs were authorized to levy taxes for the same 
 purposes. 7 In Albany the authority to levy the necessary 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 708 (1741). 
 
 2 " City Records," in Munsell, Annals of Albany, VI, 289; Colonial Laws 
 of New York, chs. 808, 826, 857. 
 
 3 After 1723 there were two bellmen in Albany; in 1731 the number 
 was increased to four, but in 1734 reduced to the former number of two. 
 
 4 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 711 (1741). 
 
 5 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 36. 
 
 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 1164 (1761). 
 
 7 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, VII, 654, ch. 9; VIII, 21, ch. 8.
 
 88 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 tax having been procured, 1 the council in 1770 appointed an 
 overseer and twenty-one watchmen. 2 The next year, how- 
 ever, twenty street lamps were purchased, and the number 
 of watchmen was reduced to six, two to be on duty every 
 third night. 3 This action strikingly emphasizes the relation 
 between street lighting and police patrol, indicated also by 
 the conjunction of the two functions in the legislative acts 
 authorizing taxation for these purposes. 
 
 Two great functions of municipal government of to-day 
 the administration of charities and of public schools were 
 almost entirely without the scope of the borough govern- 
 ments. In Philadelphia the overseers of the poor were ap- 
 pointed by the mayor, recorder, and aldermen; but else- 
 where they were separately elected, and everywhere their 
 accounts and functions were separate from the borough cor- 
 porations. Education was not yet considered a public 
 function, and in none of the boroughs does there seem to 
 have been any public schools. It is hardly necessary to add 
 that public parks and public libraries were also unknown. 
 
 On the other hand, two important officials of these early 
 days have disappeared. The town crier has his vocation 
 taken by the daily newspaper; and change of public senti- 
 ment has done away with the public whipper, an official who, 
 in Albany, at least, was always a negro slave of immense 
 size. 
 
 FINANCES 
 
 The financial operations of the colonial boroughs, as may 
 be surmised from the limited field of their operations, were 
 conducted on no very extended scale. The single fact that 
 direct taxation, though toward the end of the colonial period 
 it was used in some boroughs to a considerable extent, was 
 nowhere the main source of revenue, will indicate how limited 
 was the scope of their activities. The principal revenues 
 until the last two decades before the Revolution were derived 
 
 1 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 1426. 
 
 2 "City Records," in J. Munsell, Collections on Albany, I, 210, 211, 
 January, 1770. s Ibid., I, 226 (1771).
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 
 
 89 
 
 from fines, fees, licenses, and rents from borough property, 
 while lotteries and public subscriptions were not infrequently 
 resorted to for extraordinary expenses or to pay off an ac- 
 cumulated debt. Fines were received mainly through the 
 courts from persons found guilty of violations of ordinances 
 or colonial laws; but they were also imposed for non-atten- 
 dance at the meetings of the common council, and for refusal 
 to accept office. Fees for the grant of the freedom of the 
 city at times yielded considerable revenue in some boroughs; 
 but in Albany the fees were so low that this source could never 
 have yielded any large amount to the treasury of that city. 
 
 The rents from borough property were the largest steady 
 source of income. All of the boroughs had markets, the 
 tolls and rental from which were considerable for the times; 
 and those boroughs which owned wharves and ferries made 
 them their main sources of revenue. New York and Albany 
 also derived considerable revenue from the corporation lands, 
 the former city having large grants on Manhattan Island, 
 and the latter having early purchased from the Indians 
 certain large tracts at Schaghticoke. Not much of these 
 lands was sold during the colonial period ; 1 but a good deal 
 was leased, especially by the Albany council, thus providing 
 a steady annual source of income. 
 
 The following table showing the receipts of the New York 
 corporation from these sources for certain years will illustrate 
 their relative importance at the different dates : 
 
 RECEIPTS OF NEW YORK CITY 2 
 
 Markets 
 
 1710 
 
 
 1740 
 
 
 1766 
 440 
 
 Ferry 
 
 180 
 
 310 
 
 660 
 
 Docks 
 
 30 
 
 73 
 
 620 
 
 Licenses 
 
 52 
 
 260 
 
 428 
 
 Freedoms 
 
 10 
 
 15 
 
 
 Fines 
 
 7 
 
 
 
 Leases and Rents 
 
 15 
 
 89 
 
 
 
 294 
 
 747 
 
 2148 
 
 1 Cf . Black, Municipal Ownership of Land on Manhattan Island. 
 1 From statements in Valentine's Manual for 1859, pp. 505-509.
 
 90 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The charters of the colonial boroughs, like those granted 
 to English towns, did not give any authority to the corpora- 
 tion to levy direct taxes. But the colonial legislature early 
 adopted the policy of altering and amending the powers con- 
 ferred by the charters; and by authorizing in these amend- 
 ing acts the levy of direct taxes for special purposes, they 
 paved the way for the present system of municipal rev- 
 enue, in which direct taxation plays the most important 
 part. 
 
 The first direct tax for municipal purposes based upon a 
 formal assessment of the value of the property of the individ- 
 ual was levied by the New York corporation in 1676. This 
 and a similar tax in the following year was to pay off the debt 
 incurred in rebuilding the great dock. During the next 
 decade direct taxation was again resorted to on three or four 
 occasions, chiefly to reduce the debt. 1 In 1691 the city of 
 New York was authorized by act of the new colonial as- 
 sembly " to impose any reasonable tax upon all Houses within 
 the said city, in proportion to the benefit they shall receive 
 thereby" for the expenses of constructing sewers, vaults, 
 and street pavements. By this the system of special assess- 
 ments for "betterments" was firmly established in New 
 York finances. A law of 1699 2 authorized the corporation of 
 New York to levy a tax annually for three years; and in 
 1701 8 both New York and Albany were authorized to levy 
 a tax of not over 300 a year for the payment of representa- 
 tives in the colonial assembly, bellmen, and other necessary 
 expenses. In Albany an annual tax was levied regularly 
 from this until 1716, and again after 1724, when another 
 statute authorizing a tax of not over 60 a year was passed 
 for Albany alone. 4 New York levied the tax of 300 for 
 several years after 1701; in 1704 the amount was reduced 
 
 1 Durand, Finances of New York City, p. 20. 
 
 2 Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 82. 
 
 3 Ibid., ch. 96. 
 
 4 Ibid., ch. 454.
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 91 
 
 to 200, and shortly afterward the other income of the city 
 proved sufficient and taxation as a regular source of revenue 
 ceased. But on several occasions during the next forty 
 years taxes were levied under special acts of the legislature, 
 usually to meet some extraordinary expenditure or to pay off 
 accumulated debts. 1 
 
 About the middle of the century direct taxation became a 
 regular source of a considerable part of the revenue of New 
 York City. In 1753 a yearly tax for the purpose of maintain- 
 ing the town pumps and wells was authorized, 2 but the 
 amount of the levy was limited to 120, which was increased 
 in 1764 to 200. 3 In 1761 another tax of 1800 was au- 
 thorized to provide street lights and maintain a force of 
 night watchmen, 4 and this tax with some variation in the 
 amount from year to year became a permanent annual tax. 
 Special tax laws for Albany were passed in 1761 and 1762. 
 Beginning with 1769 the Albany council levied an annual tax 
 of 250, apparently without legislative sanction. In 1774 
 the New York City law of 1761 was duplicated for Albany 
 with the maximum placed at 160, and after that the Albany 
 levy was kept within this limit. 5 
 
 The legislatures of Pennsylvania and Virginia were equally 
 willing to grant this power of taxation to the chartered cor- 
 porations within their borders. In 1712 the city of Phila- 
 delphia was authorized to levy a tax of not over twopence 
 in the pound to pay the necessary expenses of the govern- 
 ment. 8 Fifty years later the limit was raised to threepence 
 in the pound. 7 In 1733 the Bristol council levied a tax of 
 
 1 The most important of these special acts are ch. 178 (1708) ; ch. 327 
 (1717); ch. 550 (1730); ch. 669 (1737); ch. 711 (1741). 
 
 ' Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 941 (1753). 
 
 3 Ibid., ch. 1259 (1764). 
 
 Ibid., ch. 1161 (1761); cf. also ch. 1261 (1764); ch. 1365 (1768); ch. 4 
 (1774); ch. 7 (1775). 
 
 5 Ibid., ch. 7 (1774); ch. 8 (1775); " City Records," in Munsell, Collec- 
 tions on Albany, I, 200-270. 
 
 9 Laws of Pennsylvania, ch. 176 (1712). 
 
 7 Allinson and Penrose, Philadelphia, p. 33.
 
 92 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 twopence in the pound on all estates, and six shillings a head 
 for single men. 1 
 
 In 1744 the Williamsburg authorities were given power 
 to levy a tax for the purpose of building a prison, and simi- 
 lar powers were conferred on the close corporation of Nor- 
 folk in 1752. 2 Norfolk was the first of the three Virginia 
 boroughs to receive the more extended grant to levy a tax 
 from time to time for the expense of a night watch and for 
 public lighting. 3 This was in 1763; and the year following 
 a still larger sweep of power was given to the Williams- 
 burg government, 4 which was authorized to lay taxes to 
 defray the expenses of building a court house, a market- 
 house, a prison, and contagious diseases hospitals; for pur- 
 chasing fire-engines and paying the wages of firemen; for 
 sinking public wells and placing pumps; for night watch- 
 men, and for keeping in order the streets and lanes of the 
 city. In none of these Virginia statutes was there any limit 
 on the amount of tax which might be levied. 
 
 Thus by the close of the colonial period all the more im- 
 portant of the municipal corporations had received an im- 
 portant addition to their charter powers in the authority to 
 levy taxes. As yet this power was granted only for specific 
 purposes and usually with a limitation on the amount of tax; 
 but it is evident from the readiness with which the colonial 
 legislatures changed the details of the laws that the local 
 corporations were not seriously hampered by these restric- 
 tions. If a larger tax was wanted, or one for a new purpose, 
 the necessary authority could readily be secured at the first 
 session of the assembly. 
 
 The assessment and collection of taxes was managed by 
 each borough for itself, and in consequence we find no uni- 
 form system. In Williamsburg, the council made the assess- 
 
 1 W. P. Holcomb, Pennsylvania Boroughs, p. 39. 
 1 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, V, ch. 27; VI, 264. 
 Ibid., VII, 654; ch. 9 (1763). 
 ' Ibid., VIII, 21; ch. 8 (1764).
 
 MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS IN THE COLONIES 93 
 
 ment itself, and appointed collectors. 1 In Philadelphia by 
 the Act of 1712 six assessors were to be chosen annually by 
 the voters of the city, and these assessors, in conjunction 
 with the mayor, recorder, and aldermen, formed the board 
 of assessment, and appointed tax collectors. The Albany 
 charter made both assessors and collectors elective offices; 2 
 but the city records for 1707 note that the justices of the 
 peace, pursuant to act of the assembly, appointed an assessor 
 for the first ward; and after that year assessors and col- 
 lectors were no longer chosen at the annual municipal elec- 
 tions. In New York there were no special assessors and 
 collectors for city taxes. The rating and assessment were 
 made by the vestrymen, and the church wardens acted as 
 collectors, 3 these duties being imposed on them because they 
 already performed the same work in connection with the tax 
 for poor relief. 
 
 The records of borough receipts and expenditures which are 
 available indicate the absence of any well-regulated financial 
 system during most of the colonial period. The total annual 
 expenditure of New York in the years from 1710 to 1727 
 varied from 187 to 575 ; 4 in Albany, between 1754 and 
 1764, it varied from 20 to 473. These variations were 
 due mainly to the lack of funds in the corporation treasuries 
 for several years, after which money would be raised by a 
 lottery or a specially authorized tax to pay off the accu- 
 mulated debt. In New York, however, we find a steady 
 progression in the size of the budget after the third decade 
 of the eighteenth century, and especially after 1760. In 
 1740 the total receipts were 747 ; in 1750 they were 2101 ; 
 in 1766, 6573; in 1768, 9278; and in 1769, 10,395. 
 Here, then, and probably also in Philadelphia, municipal 
 
 1 Hening, Statutes of Virginia, VIII, ch. 21 (1764). 
 
 2 J. Munsell, Annals of Albany, II, 90; IV, 144; V, 159. 
 
 3 Of. Colonial Laws of New York, ch. 1642 (1774). 
 
 4 Valentine's Manual for 1859, p. 506. The average amount for these 
 years is about 335.
 
 94 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 finance was becoming of some comparative importance 
 toward the end of the period we are considering. But in the 
 other boroughs, and even in these two most important places 
 before 1750, the per capita expenditure was far below that 
 of present-day American municipalities of the same popula- 
 tion. The low rate in the colonial boroughs was, no doubt, 
 made almost necessary by the poverty of the towns and their 
 inhabitants; but it is also to be ascribed in part to the 
 limited scope of municipal action as compared with that 
 of to-day.
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 1 
 
 ON June 26, 1902, the Supreme Court of Ohio rendered 
 three decisions which precipitated a crisis in municipal affairs 
 in that state. For, by these decisions, the court virtually 
 overruled a long line of precedents, and laid down a principle 
 under which scarcely a city in the state possessed a constitu- 
 tional government. In consequence, the legislature was sum- 
 moned in extraordinary session to enact a new municipal 
 code for all the cities and villages in the state. 
 
 The situation was unparalleled, even in American history; 
 and the task before the general assembly was, doubtless, the 
 most important single act of municipal legislation that has 
 come before an American legislature. An examination of 
 the steps leading to this situation, and of the measures taken 
 to solve the difficulties, should be of interest and significance. 
 
 To understand the situation in 1902, it is necessary to 
 begin with certain clauses in the second constitution of Ohio, 
 adopted in 1851. Under the first constitution, there had 
 been no restrictions on special legislation, and the misuse of 
 its power by the legislature led to the adoption in the new 
 instrument of three different provisions affecting municipal 
 government : 
 
 Art. II, Sec. 26. "All laws of a general nature shall have a uni- 
 form operation throughout the state." 
 
 Art. XIII, Sec. 1. " The legislature shall pass no special act con- 
 ferring corporate powers." 
 
 Art. XIII, Sec. 6. "The general assembly shall provide for the 
 organization of cities and incorporated villages by general laws, and 
 restrict their power of taxation, assessment, borrowing money, con- 
 tracting debts, and loaning their credit, so as to prevent the abuse 
 of such power." 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Michigan Law Review, I, 352 (February, 1903). 
 
 95
 
 96 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 In accordance with these provisions, the general assembly 
 in 1852 enacted a general municipal corporations act, the 
 first of its kind in the United States, which repealed all 
 of the special charters then in force. This act, however, 
 divided such corporations into four classes: cities of the 
 first class, with over 20,000 population; cities of the second 
 class, with from 5000 to 20,000 population ; incorporated vil- 
 lages; and villages incorporated for special purposes. The 
 idea of classifying municipal corporations had been suggested 
 in the constitutional convention ; and it was understood that 
 laws applying to a class of cities met the constitutional re- 
 quirements. Moreover, if the scheme of classification first 
 adopted had continued in force, there could have been little 
 or no special legislation for particular cities. It is true that 
 when the law of 1852 was enacted, Cincinnati was the only 
 city in the first class; but during the following year Cleve- 
 land came into this class, and other cities would soon have 
 further increased the number. 
 
 Almost at once, however, the general classification was 
 amended by acts applying to cities within certain population 
 limits other than those of the general law. By this means 
 before 1860 special laws had been passed for Cincinnati and 
 Cleveland, and after that date for many other cities and 
 villages, which were thus each placed indirectly in a separate 
 class for certain purposes. In 1878 a new municipal code 
 was adopted with an intricate system of classification, which 
 remained in force until overthrown by the recent decision 
 of the Supreme Court. Cities of the first class were divided 
 into three grades, with provision for a fourth grade. Cities 
 of the second class were divided into four grades. Villages 
 were divided into two classes. Under this scheme each of 
 the five chief cities was in a grade by itself. But further 
 refinements of classification followed. Grades in the second 
 class were subdivided, until eleven cities had been isolated, 
 each into a grade by itself; while still further specialization 
 was introduced by passing acts with particular population
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 97 
 
 formulas which applied usually to only a single city. More- 
 over, hundreds of acts l have been passed conferring powers 
 on particular municipal corporations by name. 
 
 Most of this municipal legislation went into effect without 
 any attempt to test its constitutionality, but when cases 
 were brought before the courts, all but the most flagrant 
 cases were upheld. In 1868, the Supreme Court decided 
 that an act conferring powers upon cities of the first class, 
 with less than 100,000 population at the last federal census, 
 had a uniform operation throughout the state, although there 
 was but one city in the class. 2 Other acts were held to be 
 constitutional on other points, without considering the 
 clauses here under discussion. 3 By this process the way 
 was paved for the broad declaration, that "under the power 
 to organize cities and villages, the general assembly is author- 
 ized to classify municipal corporations, and an act relating 
 to any such class may be one of a general nature." 4 On 
 the other hand, statutes naming particular cities were held 
 to be unconstitutional, 5 as was also an act applying to "cities 
 of the second class having a population of over 31,000 at the 
 last federal census," on the ground that Columbus was the 
 only city to which the law could ever apply. 8 
 
 At length, in the case of State v. Pugh, 7 the Supreme Court 
 defined its views more fully in these words : 
 
 " It is not to be urged against legislation, general in form, concern- 
 ing cities of a designated class or grade, that but one city in the state 
 is within the particular classification at the time of the enactment. 
 Nor is it fatal to the act in question that the belief or intent of the 
 
 1 There were 1202 from 1876 to 1892. Wilcox, Municipal Government 
 in Michigan and Ohio, p. 79. 
 
 2 Welker v. Potter, 18 Ohio St. 85. 
 
 3 Walker v. Cincinnati, 21 Ohio St. 14. 
 
 4 McGill v. State, 34 Ohio St. 270. See also State v. Brewster, 39 
 Ohio St. 653. 
 
 State v. Cincinnati, 20 Ohio St. 18; State v. Cincinnati; 23 Ohio 
 St. 445. 
 
 State v. Mitchell, 31 Ohio St. 592. 
 7 43 Ohio St. 98.
 
 98 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 individual members of the general assembly who voted for the act 
 was, that it should apply only to a particular city. ... If any other 
 city may in the future, by virtue of its increase in population, and the 
 action of its municipal authorities, ripen into a city of the same class 
 and grade, it is still a law of a general nature, and is not invalid, even 
 if it confer corporate powers. On the other hand, if it is clear that no 
 other city in the state can in the future come within its operation 
 without doing violence to the manifest object and purpose of its 
 enactment, and to the clear legislative intent, it is a local and special 
 act, however strongly the form it is made to assume may suggest its 
 general character." 
 
 From this time, the constitutionality of the intricate sys- 
 tem of classification was considered to be settled; and it was 
 only necessary for the framers of municipal measures to be 
 careful in wording their bills so that they were general in 
 form, and legally capable of adoption by other cities than 
 those for which they were primarily intended. It is true the 
 question continued to be raised at times; and on some occa- 
 sions the Supreme Court expressed its doubts whether the 
 scheme of classification was originally constitutional, but it 
 felt constrained to decide in accordance with the previous 
 cases, under the doctrine of stare decisis. 1 
 
 Meanwhile, in the guise of laws dealing with classes and 
 grades of municipalities, the government of Ohio cities was 
 regulated in the main by statutes applying only to single 
 cities. For the most part, these statutes were passed at the 
 wish of the local members, who were assumed to represent 
 the wishes of the local communities. But this method of 
 legislation not only introduced all sorts of local idiosyncrasies 
 in municipal government, destroying every semblance of a 
 general system, but it also opened the way for partisan 
 measures which dislocated the local machinery of govern- 
 ment for the sake of temporary political advantage, without 
 making progress in the direction of a satisfactory municipal 
 organization. 
 
 At the regular session of the general assembly in the spring 
 
 1 State v. Wall, 47 Ohio St. 499, 500.
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 99 
 
 of 1902 there were passed several measures making impor- 
 tant changes in the government of Cleveland and Toledo, 
 in the usual form of acts applying to grades of cities. One 
 bill transferred the control of the Cleveland parks from the 
 municipal authorities to a county board, and another, au- 
 thorizing any county auditor to apply for the appointment by 
 the state board of appraisers of a board of tax review to super- 
 sede the local body, was obviously intended for application 
 only in Cleveland. These measures were passed by the Repub- 
 lican majority in opposition to the expressed wishes both 
 of the municipal authorities and the members of the legisla- 
 ture from Cuyahoga County. For Toledo, the locally elected 
 police board was to be replaced by a bi-partisan commission, 
 appointed by the governor of the state ; while an elective 
 board of administration was also created to take over the 
 functions of several previously existing boards. These 
 changes were proposed and supported by the Toledo mem- 
 bers of the legislature, and the latter had the advantage of 
 concentrating the control of municipal public works under a 
 single authority; but the police bill was vigorously opposed 
 by the mayor and both measures were thought to be intended 
 to weaken his political influence. 
 
 These measures served to strengthen the growing opposition 
 to the notorious evasion of the constitution which made 
 them possible; and in the case of the Toledo police bill the 
 opposition resulted in a suit at law, which reopened the legal 
 question and led to the startling decision of the Supreme 
 Court. The elected police commissioners of Toledo refused 
 to surrender to the new commissioners appointed by the gov- 
 ernor. Application was then made for a writ of mandamus 
 to compel the delivery of books and papers to the state board. 
 About the same time two other cases came before the Supreme 
 Court on the same issue, that certain acts conferring cor- 
 porate powers on municipal authorities were special acts, 
 in violation of the constitution. One was an application for 
 an injunction to prevent the trustees of the Cincinnati hos-
 
 100 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 pital from issuing bonds authorized by an act specifying the 
 particular institution by name. The other was a quo war- 
 ranto proceeding, brought by the attorney-general against the 
 directors of the principal municipal departments in Cleve- 
 land for judgments of ouster, this suit involving the con- 
 stitutionality of an act of 1891 establishing the so-called 
 "federal system" in Cleveland. 
 
 The unanimous decision of the court in these cases was 
 that corporate powers were conferred ; and, in contradiction to 
 the former rulings, it was held that the statutes applying 
 to single cities were special acts, although in form applying 
 to all cities of a given class. The argument was presented 
 most fully in the Toledo case (State ex rel. Kniseley v. Jones *) ; 
 and is of special importance in contrast with the doctrine 
 laid down in the former case of State v. Pugh. Says Judge 
 Shauck, who wrote the opinion in all of these cases : 
 
 "That there has long been classification of the municipalities of the 
 state is true. It is also true that while most of the acts conferring 
 corporate powers upon separate municipalities by a classified descrip- 
 tion, instead of by name, have been passed without contest as to their 
 validity, such classification was reluctantly held by this court to be 
 permissible. But attention to the original classification and to the 
 doctrine upon which it was sustained, must lead to the conclusion 
 that the doctrine does not sustain the classification involved in the 
 present case. . . . The judicial doctrine of classification was that all 
 the cities having the same characteristic of a substantial equality of 
 population should have the same corporate power, although another 
 class might be formed upon a substantial difference in population. 
 The classification now provided affords no reason for the belief that it 
 is based upon such substantial difference in population as the judicial 
 doctrine contemplated. . . . 
 
 " In view of the trivial differences in population, and of the nature 
 of the powers conferred, it appears . . . that the present classification 
 cannot be regarded as based upon differences in population, or upon 
 any other real or supposed differences in local requirements. Its real 
 basis is found in the differing views or interests of those who promote 
 legislation for the different municipalities of the state. . . . The body 
 of legislation relating to this subject shows the legislative intent to 
 
 1 State v. Jones, 66 Ohio St. 453.
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 101 
 
 substitute isolation for classification, so that all the municipalities of 
 the state which are large enough to attract attention shall be denied 
 the protection intended to be afforded by this section of the constitu- 
 tion. . . . 
 
 "Since we cannot admit that legislative power is in its nature 
 illimitable, we must conclude that this provision of the paramount law 
 annuls the acts relating to Cleveland and Toledo if they confer corporate 
 power." 
 
 It is not necessary here to follow the argument on the ques- 
 tion of conferring corporate power. This was shown to the 
 satisfaction of the court, and judgment rendered accordingly. 
 
 The decision in the Toledo and Cincinnati cases simply 
 declared void new statutes, and left the previous laws in 
 force. But in the Cleveland case, to have authorized imme- 
 diate execution of the judgment would have overturned a 
 system of ten years' standing, and left the city with no execu- 
 tive officials. The court therefore suspended execution in 
 order to " give to those discharging the duties of the other de- 
 partments of the government of the state an opportunity to 
 take such action as to them may seem best, in view of the 
 condition which the execution of our judgment will create." 
 
 The action which the judgment of the court made impera- 
 tive was nothing less than the enactment of a new municipal 
 code for all the cities and villages in the state. For, not 
 only could the Cleveland situation be remedied in no other 
 way, but the principle laid down by the court announced 
 the whole body of municipal legislation as unconstitutional. 
 Accordingly the governor summoned the general assembly 
 to meet in extraordinary session on August 25, to enact the 
 necessary legislation. 
 
 While the decision of the Supreme Court was both startling, 
 and on the whole unexpected, it cannot be said that the legis- 
 lature was altogether unprepared for the situation. For 
 years the obvious evasion of the constitutional provisions 
 had been recognized, both by laymen and lawyers, and serious 
 efforts had been made to secure a general municipal code. 
 
 In 1898 there had been created by the legislature a com-
 
 102 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 mission of two lawyers, differing in their party allegiance, 
 who were authorized to draft a bill. After two years of labor, 
 this commission presented an elaborate measure, known 
 generally as the Pugh-Kibler code, from the names of the 
 members of the commission. This bill abolished the classifi- 
 cation of cities, and established a council of seven members 
 as the legislative body in each city. It separated legislative 
 from the administrative functions, and organized the ad- 
 ministrative authorities on the same principles as govern 
 the federal administration, which had already been applied 
 to some extent in Cleveland and Columbus. Under this 
 scheme each municipal department was placed under the 
 control of a single official or director, appointed by the mayor. 
 The bill further provided for a comprehensive application 
 of the merit system in the appointment of all subordinate 
 officers and employees, and for the abolition of the party 
 column in ballots for municipal elections. 
 
 This bill was introduced in the general assembly in 1900, 
 and with some amendments again in 1902. But, although 
 endorsed by the state bar association, it failed to receive 
 adequate consideration. It must be confessed that there 
 was little popular demand for the radical changes in organi- 
 zation proposed ; but the more potent obstacle seems to have 
 been the provisions for a stringent merit system and for non- 
 partisan elections, which were naturally not favored by the 
 politicians who profited by the existing methods. There 
 was little active debate on the merits of the bill, but by 
 the policy of neglect nothing effective was accomplished. 
 Nevertheless, a well-considered bill had been prepared and 
 given some attention, and it might have been expected that 
 the principles of this measure would have received serious 
 consideration when the question was forced on the legislature 
 at its special session. 
 
 In the interval before the general assembly came together, 
 the governor took the lead in framing a bill which became 
 the text for discussions in the legislature. This activity of
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 103 
 
 the governor in framing legislation marks a striking excep- 
 tion to the theory of the separation of legislative and ex- 
 ecutive powers, and a notable departure from the older 
 American practice, the more significant because in Ohio the 
 governor did not then possess the veto power. 
 
 The governor consulted with a number of Republican mem- 
 bers of the legislature from different cities in the state, but 
 this included no representation from either Cleveland or 
 Columbus, while the most active part in framing the governor's 
 bill was taken by legislators and city officials from Cincinnati. 
 The result was a bill framed to a large extent on the existing 
 organization in Cincinnati, an organization which had been 
 the outcome of heterogeneous piecemeal legislation, and had 
 never been considered elsewhere as a model, or even as a con- 
 sistent system of municipal government. 
 
 One feature of the Cincinnati government, which it was 
 understood the governor wished to extend, was early aban- 
 doned, but only to reappear under another form in the code 
 finally adopted. This was the control of the police by a 
 bi-partisan board appointed by the governor. Instead, a 
 bi-partisan board of public safety, appointed by the mayor, 
 was provided to have control of the police and fire-depart- 
 ments. Each city was also to have an elected board of public 
 service, to have charge of public works, health, charitable 
 institutions, and libraries. Other officers were to be ap- 
 pointed by the mayor, except the treasurer and auditor. 
 The council was to have a small proportion of its members 
 elected on a general ticket. All of the city officials, except 
 members of the board of public safety, were to have three- 
 year terms, and to be chosen at the triennial spring election. 
 This scheme of organization was to be established in every 
 city in the state, and every municipal corporation of over 
 5000 population was to be a city. 
 
 When the general assembly met, the governor's bill was 
 promptly introduced in both houses. The Senate proceeded 
 to consider it in committee of the whole, and after a very
 
 104 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 cursory discussion passed the bill with a few minor amend- 
 ments, on September 30. The House, however, showed 
 a more thorough appreciation of its duties, and gave more 
 serious consideration to the measure. A committee of twenty- 
 two members was appointed, which held public sessions for 
 more than two weeks, at which city officials and others inter- 
 ested presented their opinions; after which the committee 
 framed a bill of its own differing in important respects from 
 that of the governor. 
 
 The most important changes to be noted were the substitu- 
 tion of single directors, to be elected by popular vote, in 
 place of the boards of public safety and of public service, 
 and provisions for the application of the merit system in 
 the selection of the members of the police and fire depart- 
 ments. Other bills had also been introduced: one providing 
 for the "federal system" of organization, as in the Pugh- 
 Kibler code; and another, supported by the state chamber 
 of commerce, authorized each city to frame its own charter 
 in a local convention. The latter measure was said to con- 
 flict with the constitutional provision requiring the legisla- 
 ture to provide for the organization of municipalities. The 
 "federal system" did not find favor with the majority, 
 mainly on account of political conditions. The two cities 
 where some features of this plan were in operation (Cleve- 
 land and Columbus) had elected Democratic mayors; and 
 although leading Cleveland Republicans upheld the system, 
 there was apparently an undercurrent of feeling that in some 
 way its general adoption might strengthen the Democratic 
 party. More specifically the Republican leaders were believed 
 to be anxious to weaken the political influence of the mayor 
 of Cleveland, who had become the leader of the Democrats 
 throughout the state. This injection of state and national 
 politics prevented any fair consideration of the " federal 
 plan" on its merits as a system of municipal government. 
 
 On October 7, the bill of the House committee, amended 
 somewhat in the House, was passed by that body. Owing
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 105 
 
 to the important differences between the bills as passed by 
 the Senate and House, a conference committee was appointed. 
 Here for two weeks the proposed code was further discussed; 
 and, contrary to the usual custom of conference committees, 
 the sessions were for the most part public, in the sense that 
 newspaper representatives were present and the proceedings 
 and conclusions were published from day to day. The pro- 
 ceedings showed an astonishing lack of consistency on the 
 part of the conference committee. The House bill was taken 
 as the foundation of their work, but this was freely amended 
 and reamended. Votes taken on a particular section were 
 often reconsidered ; and some sections were completely recast, 
 not only once, but several times, on entirely distinct lines. 
 Rumors of outside influences at work were freely circulated; 
 and in particular a United States senator and the Republican 
 "boss" of Cincinnati were alleged to have dictated the final 
 form of the measure. Finally the conference committee 
 made its report, and on October 22, the code became law. 
 The final vote in the Senate, 21 to 12, was strictly on party 
 lines. In the House, three Democrats voted for the bill, and 
 the vote stood 65 to 34. The opposition of the Democrats 
 prevented the enactment of new provisions for municipal 
 courts, as under the Ohio constitution legislation establishing 
 judicial courts requires the affirmative vote of two-thirds 
 of the members of each house. 
 
 As adopted, the municipal code contains most of the features 
 of the governor's bill, but with some serious alterations and 
 considerable additions. The council in each city will be a 
 single house, the number of members varying with the popu- 
 lation, elected partly by wards and partly on general ticket. 
 The elective officers consist of a mayor, president of the coun- 
 cil, treasurer, auditor, solicitor, and a board of public service 
 of three or five members. All of these are chosen for two- 
 year terms, except the auditor, whose tenure is for three years. 1 
 
 1 The auditor's term has since been changed to two years and all the 
 elective officers are chosen at the same time.
 
 106 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Other officers provided for by the code are to be appointed 
 by the mayor, but subject to varying restrictions. The 
 board of public safety of two or four members must be bi- 
 partisan, and the mayor's nominations must be confirmed 
 by two-thirds of the council, failing which the governor of 
 the state is to make the appointments. This board is to 
 make contracts and rules for the police and fire departments; 
 and is also to act as a merit commission to examine candidates 
 and prepare eligible lists for positions in these departments. 
 From these lists of eligibles, the mayor is to make appoint- 
 ments and promotions. The board of health is to be ap- 
 pointed by the mayor with the confirmation of the council. 
 A sinking fund and tax commission of four members and a 
 library board of six members are to be appointed by the 
 mayor. The mayor will have a limited veto power, which 
 may be overridden by a two-thirds vote of the council. The 
 board of public service will have complete charge of all public 
 works and municipal improvements, including the power 
 to make contracts, to" determine its own subordinates, fix 
 their salaries and make appointments, subject only to the 
 council's power to limit appropriations. 
 
 This scheme of organization, which went into effect in 
 April, 1903, applied uniformly to all the seventy-two cities 
 of over 5000 population. The organization of villages was 
 left very much as under the former law. 
 
 A critical examination of the code enacted reveals some 
 features to be commended as improvements over the preced- 
 ing conditions in Ohio, but also shows many points of weak- 
 ness; and on the whole the code fails to establish a satis- 
 factory permanent system of municipal government. 
 
 The changes for the better may be first noted. Of these, 
 the most important is clearly the advantage of a uniform 
 general system over the complicated variety of statutory 
 provisions enacted under the former schemes of classifica- 
 tion. The law of municipal corporations in Ohio is now dis- 
 tinctly simpler and more intelligible; the principal municipal
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 107 
 
 officers and their functions will be the same in each city; 
 and the bulk of municipal legislation has been greatly re- 
 duced. While the general powers conferred on cities do not 
 authorize any experiments, every city in the state may now 
 exercise all the powers which have been assumed in any city. 
 Thus municipal lighting plants and municipal universities 
 are within the scope of any city without further legislative 
 action. In the organization provided, the plan for electing 
 some members of the municipal councils at large offers an 
 opportunity for strengthening that branch of the municipal 
 government. Defective as is the board system established, 
 it is also true that the board of public service does in some 
 cities absorb the functions of several existing boards, and 
 thus to some extent simplifies the municipal organization. 
 And the limited provision for the application of the merit 
 system, ineffective as it seems likely to prove, is at least a 
 slight concession to the demand for a more stable municipal 
 service free from the influence of the spoils system. 
 
 But when these improvements have been noted, there 
 remains a much longer list of indefensible features and neg- 
 lected opportunities. The broadest charge made against 
 the code is that it does not grant an adequate measure of 
 home rule; but this charge is too indefinite, and must be 
 made more specific and discriminating. Extreme advocates 
 of municipal independence will probably urge that the whole 
 question of municipal organization should be left for each 
 city to determine for itself; and that in place of a list of enu- 
 merated powers each city should have unlimited authority 
 to undertake any function it pleases. But apart from the 
 question of policy, certain legal facts stood in the way of 
 any such proposals. On the one point, there were and are 
 strong grounds for believing that the mandatory provisions 
 of the Ohio constitution requiring the legislature to provide 
 for the organization of municipalities prohibits any delega- 
 tion of organizing powers to the cities. On the other point, 
 stands a long line of judicial decisions limiting municipal
 
 108 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 powers to those expressly granted by statute. Under these 
 circumstances, if a wisely devised scheme of organization 
 had been provided, with an ample list of specified powers and 
 the selection of officers left to each city, the code would have 
 met all reasonable requirements for municipal home rule. 
 
 But these conditions are, in fact, far from being fulfilled. 
 The specific powers granted are not adequate to modern 
 conditions. In particular, there is no authority under which 
 a city can assume the ownership and operation of street rail- 
 ways or other undertakings requiring the use of the public 
 streets; for, without advocating municipal ownership as a 
 general rule, it may safely be said that each city should have 
 the power, under suitable restrictions, to determine such 
 questions for itself. The rule for local selection of officers 
 meets with a serious exception in the provisions in reference 
 to the board of safety, which were obviously adopted for 
 distinctly partisan purposes. When the mayor's nomina- 
 tions for this board are not confirmed by a two-thirds vote 
 of the council, the governor is to make the appointments. 
 Apparently, the sole purpose of this provision is to give a 
 Republican governor the power of appointing these boards in 
 Democratic cities; as it is believed that the Republicans will 
 have at least one-third of the members of the councils in 
 these cities, and thus be able to prevent confirmation of the 
 mayor's nominations. A device of this kind cannot be de- 
 fended, and is sufficient in itself to warrant severe criticism 
 of the code. And this attitude is taken with a full admission 
 of the fact that police affairs are not only of local, but also of 
 general, interest, justifying state supervision. But that super- 
 vision should be extended to all localities on a uniform basis, 
 and in accordance with the principles followed in the state 
 supervision of local school and health authorities. 
 
 When the scheme of municipal organization provided in 
 the code is examined in detail, it can be seen at once that 
 little or nothing has been adopted from recent discussions 
 or from recent legislation in other states dealing with this
 
 THE MUNICIPAL CRISIS IN OHIO 109 
 
 problem. The list of elective officers is too numerous to 
 permit the voters, especially in a large city, to learn the quali- 
 fications of the various candidates; and the result will inevi- 
 tably be the continuation of party tickets and party voting. 
 The number of elective officers also prevents the concentra- 
 tion of responsibility for the municipal administration as 
 a whole. The diffusion of responsibility is more thorough 
 by the complicated system of boards for the various branches 
 of administration, while there is a complete absence of any 
 method for securing the harmonious cooperation of the vari- 
 ous departmental officers. It will be noted that there is not 
 even a uniform system of boards established, but the differ- 
 ent boards represent almost every conceivable method of 
 board organization. The board of public safety, in particular, 
 is a strange creation. Combining as it does the power to 
 make contracts and to act as a merit commission, it is almost 
 certain that the latter function will be subordinated to the 
 former, and it is very doubtful if the provisions for a merit 
 system of appointments will be effectively executed. More- 
 over, these provisions apply only to the police and fire depart- 
 ments; and all other branches of the municipal service are 
 left entirely free to the continuation of the spoils system. 
 
 Two motives seem to have played the leading part in bring- 
 ing about these results. On the one hand, the political 
 powers in Cincinnati wished to preserve the machinery in 
 operation in that city as much as possible, since they knew 
 how it worked and how it could be controlled. On the other 
 hand, the alleged desire to weaken the political influence of 
 the mayor of Cleveland roused opposition to any suggestions 
 in the direction of concentrating power and responsibility 
 in the hands of the mayor.
 
 VI 
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 1 
 
 IN every country the organization and powers of municipal 
 corporations have at first been regulated by special laws or 
 charters for each community. But in the course of time 
 the tendency has been to establish a general and more or less 
 uniform system within each organized government. Thus 
 in ancient history the early self-constituted city governments 
 in the Italian peninsula were reorganized after the extension 
 of the Roman dominion, about the time of Sulla, and the 
 main features of this municipal system were later extended 
 throughout the Roman Empire. After the breakdown of 
 that empire, special charters again appeared throughout 
 western Europe. But since the end of the eighteenth century 
 these have been replaced in practically all the European 
 countries by general municipal codes. France led the way 
 in this movement, at the time of the Revolution. Prussia 
 followed this example in 1808 and England in 1835. Other 
 countries have one after another adopted the same method 
 of procedure. 
 
 Special charters and special acts of the legislatures were 
 the only methods of organizing municipal government in the 
 United States until the middle of the nineteenth century. 
 In 1851 the second constitution of the state of Ohio began 
 the attempt to secure general laws by prohibiting special 
 legislation. Other states adopted similar provisions in their 
 constitutions, at first slowly, but more rapidly since 1870. 
 And now most of the states attempt in one way or another 
 to prohibit or restrict special legislation on municipal govern- 
 ment. A few, however, such as Massachusetts and Michigan, 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Political Science Quarterly, XXI, 434 (Septem- 
 ber, 1906). 
 
 110
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 111 
 
 have no constitutional restrictions, and special charters are 
 still openly and freely enacted. 
 
 But even in most of the states where special legislation is 
 prohibited there have been no comprehensive systems of 
 municipal organization established. By the device of classi- 
 fication, laws general in form have been enacted, which, in 
 fact, applied only to single cities. Until within a few years 
 such laws have been generally accepted as complying with 
 the constitutional provisions. As a result, there is nothing 
 approaching uniformity or system in the government of 
 cities in most of the states. And for the country as a whole 
 the diversities have been so numerous and so far-reaching 
 that any attempt to describe the typical American municipal 
 organization has been impossible. 
 
 A few states, however, are now exceptions to this rule. 
 Three of these are the neighboring states of Illinois, Ohio, 
 and Indiana, forming a compact group in the central part 
 of the country. The Illinois law was enacted in 1872, and 
 was probably the first effective municipal code in the United 
 States. Ohio and Indiana have also had nominal codes for 
 a long time; but the schemes of classification were so highly 
 developed as to prevent any general system of organization. 
 But within a few years both of these states have enacted 
 new municipal codes establishing a general plan. This 
 recent legislation suggests a comparative study of the codes 
 of the three states. While these states agree in the method 
 of dealing with the problem, and while the systems adopted 
 have some features in common, illustrating present ten- 
 dencies throughout the United States, there are also many 
 and wide divergencies which show the absence of any con- 
 sensus of opinion on this question among American legisla- 
 tors. 
 
 ILLINOIS 
 
 The Illinois Cities and Villages Act is said to have been 
 drafted by the late Judge M. F. Tuley, of Chicago. At the 
 time of its enactment it was undoubtedly the best and most
 
 112 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 successful measure on the subject of municipal government 
 that had been adopted in the United States. It has been 
 amended from time to time, but its main features have been 
 unaltered. And while it has proven inadequate to meet 
 some of the conditions that have since developed, it still 
 contains much that is worthy of study by the legislators of 
 other states. 
 
 A comparatively simple and elastic plan of municipal 
 organization is provided by this act. In every city there 
 must be elected a city council, a mayor, a city clerk, a city 
 attorney, and a city treasurer. Other officers may be created 
 by the city council as needed. 
 
 Members of the council are elected by wards, two from 
 each ward, for a term of two years, one alderman from each 
 ward retiring each year. Their number varies from six to 
 seventy, according to the size of the city. The powers of 
 the council include a long list of enumerated subjects of 
 police regulation, such as is usual in city charters; the power 
 of making appropriations and a limited power of taxation; 
 and the unusual power to create municipal offices. The 
 latter power requires a two-thirds vote of all the members 
 of the council, and offices so created may be abolished only 
 by a similar vote at the end of a fiscal year. This restriction 
 and the provisions by which the council cannot itself make 
 appointments to offices has prevented any abuse of the power 
 to create offices. The control over appropriations is also 
 an important power actively exercised by the council, in the 
 large cities mainly through the finance committee. These 
 two special powers make the councils of Illinois cities much 
 more important factors in the municipal organization than in 
 other American cities. 
 
 But the mayor also has important powers. He is elected 
 for two years, 1 presides over the city council, has the usual 
 limited veto power, and has large authority over the ap- 
 
 1 By a special law passed under the recent constitutional amendment 
 the mayor of Chicago is now elected for four years.
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 113 
 
 pointment and control of the city officers. His appoint- 
 ments to office must be confirmed by the council, but usually 
 this confirmation has been given without question, and in 
 Chicago, at least generally, without even reference to a com- 
 mittee. His control over the appointed officers is further 
 established by his large power of removal. This is not 
 entirely unlimited, as he is required to file the reasons for 
 removal with the council, and if he fails to do so, or if the 
 council by a two-thirds vote disapproves of the removal, the 
 officer is reinstated. But these restrictions are not likely 
 to be effective except in the case of a gross abuse of the 
 removal power; and in fact the mayor has a very substantial 
 control over the city officers, and can be held responsible for 
 the conduct of the administrative branch of the city govern- 
 ment. 
 
 Popular election of the city clerk, city attorney, and city 
 treasurer shows the influence of the earlier movement for the 
 election of all city officers. At the time the Illinois law was 
 enacted, this was a smaller number of elective officers than 
 was common in most American cities. But at present the 
 trend of intelligent opinion on municipal organization would 
 favor making at least the clerk and attorney appointive in 
 the interest of administrative efficiency. In fact, Chicago 
 and perhaps other cities have established the appointive 
 office of corporation counsel, and the office of city attorney 
 has become of little importance. 
 
 The most serious weakness of the Illinois law is the narrow 
 limit placed on the power of taxation, which has prevented 
 the city governments from developing their activity to meet 
 the needs of increased population. This has, in turn, promoted 
 the tendency to create by additional legislation special au- 
 thorities independent of the city governments to undertake 
 certain local works, which might better have been intrusted 
 to the city corporation. Thus, not only boards of education, 
 but library boards, park boards, and the sanitary trustees 
 in Cook County are separate corporations, adding greatly to
 
 114 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the complexity of local government, tending to confuse the 
 voters with a multiplicity of elective officers and reducing 
 the effective responsibility to the community of these special 
 officials. 
 
 Chicago has suffered most from the limitation on financial 
 powers and the multiplication of authorities. With forty 
 times the population of any other city in the state, the met- 
 ropolitan community has had to meet problems that have 
 not begun to arise in the smaller cities. The unsatisfactory 
 local situation, with the difficulty of securing adequate changes 
 in the general law, has led to the adoption of a constitutional 
 amendment authorizing special legislation for Chicago, subject 
 to approval by a referendum vote. 1 
 
 Doubtless some special provisions are almost necessary for 
 a city so vastly different as is Chicago from the others in the 
 state. But many of the difficulties affect the smaller places 
 only in a less degree; and many of the changes to be made 
 ought to be made in the general law. And it is to be regretted 
 that the ability of Illinois legislators has so far declined 
 and they seem unable to perfect and adapt to modern con- 
 ditions the excellent law that was passed over thirty years 
 ago. 
 
 OHIO 
 
 The second constitution of Ohio, adopted in 1851, made 
 the first attempt in the United States to prohibit special 
 legislation for cities and to require the establishment of a 
 general system of municipal organization. But by the de- 
 vice of classifying cities on the basis of population, all the 
 larger cities in the state had many peculiar factors in their 
 municipal government, established by laws which, in fact, 
 applied only to single cities. And for over fifty years the 
 Supreme Court of the state accepted laws of this kind, general 
 
 1 A new charter for Chicago, framed by a local commission, was passed, 
 with some amendments, at the last session of the legislature, only to be 
 defeated at the referendum vote in September, 1907.
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 115 
 
 in form, but special in their application, as complying with 
 the constitutional provisions. 1 
 
 In 1902, however, the Supreme Court practically reversed 
 its former attitude and held that the whole body of legislation 
 on municipal government disclosed the legislative intent to 
 substitute isolation for classification. Certain acts brought 
 before the court were declared unconstitutional, and the 
 opinion showed that most of the legislation on cities would be 
 held unconstitutional if brought before it. 2 This situation 
 led to a special session of the state legislature, which enacted 
 a new municipal code for all the cities and villages in Ohio. 
 In framing the original draft of the bill, Governor Bushnell 
 took an active part ; and in the work of the conference com- 
 mittee to decide conflicts between the two houses, the final 
 determination was said to have been due in large measure to 
 the influence of a United States senator and the leader of 
 the then dominant political organization in Cincinnati. 
 
 The Ohio code is much more detailed than the Illinois law. 
 It provides a numerous and complicated list of elective offices, 
 burdensome to the small cities, and with a lack of effective 
 organization and clearly defined responsibility. 
 
 Cities are defined as municipal corporations of over 5000 
 population, and the same organization is applied to all the 
 seventy-two cities in the state. The city council consists of 
 a single chamber, the number of members varying with the 
 population. The larger number of members are elected by 
 wards, each electing one councilman; but a small number 
 are also elected on a general ticket for the whole city. The 
 powers of the council are restricted to those of a legislative 
 character; and it is expressly provided that it shall perform 
 no administrative duties and exercise no appointing power, 
 except in regard to its own organization and in confirming 
 nominations to certain positions named in the act. The 
 
 1 State v. Pugh, 43 Ohio St. 98. 
 
 1 State v. Jones, 66 Ohio St. 453. 
 
 3 Wade H. Ellis, The Municipal Code of Ohio.
 
 116 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 powers granted include authority to enact police ordinances, 
 to vote appropriations and taxes, to determine the number 
 of members on certain municipal boards, and to fix the salaries 
 and bonds of the statutory municipal officers. But there is 
 no power to create municipal officers similar to that in the 
 Illinois law; and even the establishment of minor positions 
 is given to the executive officers. It may by a two-thirds 
 vote remove officers after a trial on definite charges. 
 
 The mayor is elected for a term of two years. He has a 
 limited veto power and a very restricted power over the 
 selection of officials. Most of the important officers are 
 elective; but the mayor nominates, subject to the confirma- 
 tion of the council, members of the boards of public safety 
 and health, and appoints the members of the tax commission 
 and the library board. It is made his duty to have a general 
 supervision over all departments and city officers; but he 
 has no power of removal or any other effective means of 
 control over their actions. The narrow range of his authority 
 is further indicated by the provision which vests executive 
 power, not in the mayor, but in the list of elective and ap- 
 pointed executive officers. 
 
 Other elective officers are the treasurer, auditor, solicitor, 
 and the board of public service, all elected for two years. The 
 board of public service is the most significant of these. It 
 consists of three or five members; and has charge of streets, 
 sewers, and other public improvements, of municipal water 
 and lighting plants, parks, markets, cemeteries, and of all 
 charitable and correctional institutions. 
 
 Of the appointed officers, the board of public safety is 
 provided for in a very peculiar way. This is a bi-partisan 
 board of two or four members, having supervision over the 
 police and fire departments. Its members are appointed on 
 the nomination of the mayor subject to the confirmation of 
 two-thirds of the council, and failing this confirmation, ap- 
 pointments are made by the governor of the state. This 
 method was apparently adopted for political purposes, and
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 117 
 
 under it the boards of public safety in about a dozen cities 
 have been appointed by the governor. 
 
 The board of tax commissioners is also a bi-partisan body, 
 consisting of four members appointed by the mayor, serving 
 without compensation. To this board are referred the tax 
 levies ordered by the council to cover its appropriations, and 
 if it disapproves any item of the appropriation, the tax levy 
 must be reduced, unless the action of the board is overruled 
 by a three-fourths vote of all the members of the council. 
 The board also acts as a sinking-fund commission. 
 
 By establishing a general system of municipal organization 
 and uniform powers, this code makes the law of municipal 
 corporations in Ohio much simpler and more intelligible than 
 formerly. The volume of legislation on municipal govern- 
 ment is greatly reduced, and litigation to determine the 
 meaning or constitutionality of disputed points is also lessened, 
 since a decision for one city determines the point for all. 
 The scope of municipal activities has not been enlarged, but 
 every city may, without further legislative action, exercise all 
 the powers that have been granted to any one. 
 
 In the organization of the council the plan of electing some 
 members at large offers an opportunity for strengthening that 
 branch of the municipal government. But the system of 
 artificial and changeable wards is also retained, with its 
 opportunities for gerrymandering. The board of public 
 service absorbs the functions formerly given in many cities 
 to a number of boards, and thus simplifies to some extent 
 the municipal organization. 1 But it may be questioned 
 whether in the large cities this has not placed in one depart- 
 ment too many unrelated services. The provisions authoriz- 
 ing the merit system in the police and fire departments are 
 
 1 The board of public service bears a slight resemblance to some fea- 
 tures of the " commission plan " recently authorized in Texas, Kansas, 
 and Iowa, in concentrating administrative powers in the hands of a 
 small board. But in Ohio, the mayor and council still remain with some 
 powers ; and, in contrast with the Iowa law, the boards in Ohio cities are 
 elected on party tickets, with free scope for patronage appointments.
 
 118 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 at least a slight concession to the demand for eliminating 
 spoils politics from the municipal service. 
 
 But in other respects this code is open to serious criticism. 
 The number of municipal officers required in all cities is too 
 cumbersome for many of the small cities, and the city council 
 might well have been given authority to create offices as 
 needed, as in the Illinois law. The number of elective officers 
 is too large to permit the voters to learn the qualifications 
 of the various candidates, and this tends to reduce popular 
 control and increase the influence of party organizations. The 
 variety in the methods of filling various offices prevents the 
 concentration of responsibility, and in particular the au- 
 thority of the mayor is inadequate. No provision is made 
 for the merit system for the larger proportion of municipal 
 employees, who are placed under the control of the board of 
 public service. 
 
 Since this code was adopted, there have been two sessions 
 of the Ohio legislature. At each of these some minor amend- 
 ments have been passed. The most important is the change 
 in the date of municipal elections from April to November 
 in the odd years. By changing the date of state elections in 
 the future to the even years, municipal elections will be 
 kept distinct from state and national elections; and with 
 that provision there is perhaps some advantage in having 
 all elections come in the fall. During the session of 1906 an 
 effort was made to make some more important changes in the 
 system of organization, especially by increasing the powers of 
 the mayor. But nothing was accomplished. 
 
 INDIANA 
 
 In 1905 a general revision of the Indiana municipal law was 
 enacted by the legislature of that state. There was little 
 public discussion, and apparently no partisan motives affected 
 the measure. The code as enacted simplifies somewhat the 
 system of organization, and applies to all but the smallest 
 places the centralized plan of mayoralty control which had 
 been previously established in the larger cities.
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 119 
 
 One of the most important changes was the abolition of 
 spring city elections and the extension of the terms of city 
 officers from two to four years. The terms of officers which 
 would have expired in the spring of 1905 were continued 
 until the following January; and, beginning in 1905, an 
 election will be held for city officers in November of every 
 fourth year. While spring elections are abolished, municipal 
 elections are not combined with state and national elections, 
 but, as in Ohio, come in an intervening year. Another pro- 
 vision making all elective officers ineligible for two terms in 
 succession will, however, hinder the development of a con- 
 tinuous policy and seems entirely uncalled for, at least in 
 the case of the members of the councils and the city clerk. 
 
 Municipal corporations are divided into two main classes: 
 incorporated towns and cities. Any community may by 
 popular vote be incorporated as a town; any community 
 with more than 2500 population may become a city ; and both 
 cities and towns may be dissolved by popular vote. 
 
 A very simple system of organization is provided for the 
 incorporated towns. Provision is made for the election of 
 a board of trustees of three to seven members, one for each 
 ward, but all elected at large ; also for the election of a clerk 
 and treasurer, or one person to act in both capacities. The 
 trustees shall elect one of their number as president, shall 
 appoint a marshal, who may also act as street commissioner 
 and chief of the fire force, and shall have general charge of 
 municipal matters in the town. 
 
 Cities are divided into five classes on the basis of popu- 
 lation at the latest United States census, but the systems 
 of government for the different classes are along similar 
 lines. The first class includes cities over 100,000 population, 
 of which Indianapolis is the only instance. The second 
 class includes cities from 45,000 to 100,000, of which at pres- 
 ent there are two Evansville and Fort Wayne. The 
 third class, from 20,000 to 45,000, has five cities Terre 
 Haute, South Bend, Muncie, New Albany, and Anderson.
 
 120 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The fourth class, from 10,000 to 20,000, has eleven cities; 
 and the fifth class, those under 10,000, includes about fifty 
 cities. 
 
 Variations in organization provided in the act are, however, 
 less frequent than the number of classes. The arrangements 
 for the first two classes are practically identical; and also 
 those for the third and fourth classes. There seems no sub- 
 stantial reason why there should have been more than three 
 classes established. 
 
 Every city elects a council, a mayor, and a city clerk. A 
 city judge is also to be elected, except in cities of the fifth 
 class, where the mayor acts in that capacity. A city treasurer 
 is elected, except in cities of the first three classes, which are 
 county seats, where the county treasurer acts as city treasurer. 
 
 The council consists of one member from each ward, and 
 from two to six members elected at large, the number of 
 members at large to be half as many as the number elected 
 by wards. Boundaries of wards may be changed once in six 
 years by a two-thirds vote of all members of the council. 
 The powers of the council include authority to establish 
 police regulations in a long list of enumerated cases. New 
 features in this list are the power to exclude saloons from the 
 residence portions of cities, the power to regulate the height 
 of buildings, and the power to regulate railroad traffic within 
 the city limits. The council can also levy taxes, vote loans 
 up to two per cent of the taxable value of property, and 
 manage the finances. But it is provided that if a council 
 fails to fix the tax levy and make appropriations before the 
 first Monday of October, the levy and appropriations for 
 the preceding year shall be continued and renewed for the 
 current year. In cities of the fifth class council committees 
 may exercise executive functions. 
 
 The mayor is given important and far-reaching powers. 
 He has the absolute power of appointing the heads of all 
 departments in cities of the first four classes, and most of 
 the executive officers in cities of the fifth class. These
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 121 
 
 officers will not hold for any specified term, but any of them 
 may be removed by the mayor, who is required to give notice 
 to the officer and to state in a message to the council the 
 reason for removal. This arrangement clearly makes the 
 mayor responsible for the conduct of the executive depart- 
 ments, but at the same time encourages permanence of 
 tenure in the management of these departments by requir- 
 ing the mayor to state publicly his reasons for exercising the 
 power of removal. This system is moreover not introduced 
 on purely theoretical grounds, but has already proven its 
 practical advantages in a number of the larger Indiana cities. 
 
 Monthly meetings of the mayor and heads of departments 
 are provided for, and this "cabinet" is authorized to adopt 
 rules and regulations for the administration of the depart- 
 ments, including rules " which shall prescribe a common and 
 systematic method of ascertaining the comparative fitness 
 of applicants for office, position, and promotion, and of select- 
 ing, appointing, and promoting those found to be best fitted." 
 
 The mayor has also the usual limited veto power, including 
 the right to veto items of appropriation bills, the power to 
 recommend measures to the council and to call special sessions 
 of that body. In cities of the third, fourth, and fifth classes 
 he presides over the council; he can also appoint special 
 examiners to investigate the accounts of any department or 
 officer at any time. 
 
 Executive officers and departments are regulated in con- 
 siderable detail by the act, with variations for the different 
 classes of cities. But in the main a uniform method is fol- 
 lowed. 
 
 In cities of the fifth class there is a marshal, chief of fire 
 force, street commissioner, and board of health and charities 
 appointed by the mayor, and a city attorney appointed 
 by the council. Other executive functions are performed in 
 these cities by council committees. 
 
 In the cities of the first four classes there are from five to 
 eight departments. All cities in these classes have depart-
 
 122 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ments of finance, law, public works, assessment and collection, 
 and public health and charities. A department of public 
 safety, controlling the police and fire force, is provided for 
 cities of the first and second class, and is optional for cities 
 of the third class. The variation seems to be due to the pro- 
 vision in the former law for state police boards in cities from 
 10,000 to 35,000 population. A special department of public 
 parks is also provided for cities of the first two classes. By a 
 peculiar arrangement cities of the second class are allowed 
 to establish a special department of waterworks, which in 
 other cities comes under the department of public works. 
 
 The departments of finance, law, and assessment and collec- 
 tion are placed in charge of single officials the comptroller, 
 city attorney, and the elected treasurer. The assessment 
 of property for taxation is, however, not regulated by the 
 municipal code, but by a general law on the subject for the 
 whole state. Where a city establishes a sinking fund, there 
 is provided a sinking-fund commission, consisting of the comp- 
 troller and two other members appointed by the mayor in 
 this case the terms of the latter two members expiring at 
 different times. 
 
 The other departments are in charge of boards, consisting 
 of three members each, except for the park boards, which 
 have four members. In all cases not more than two mem- 
 bers of each board may belong to the same political party. 
 
 Salaries are regulated for the various classes of cities with 
 too much detail. In some cases maximum salaries are speci- 
 fied; in others a minimum and maximum. But there is 
 little discretion left to the councils; and with the growth 
 of cities it is certain that there will be frequent amendments 
 to the law in this respect. Of the boards, that for public 
 works is allowed the largest remuneration; the board of 
 public safety has a distinctly smaller rate; the board of 
 health has a maximum of one hundred dollars for each 
 member, while the park board must serve without compen- 
 sation.
 
 MUNICIPAL CODES IN THE MIDDLE WEST 123 
 
 If municipal departments must be regulated by statute, 
 the Indiana plan of varying the system with a reasonable 
 classification of cities is much better than the hard and fast 
 provisions for all cities in the Ohio law. But in this respect 
 the Illinois act, which permits the city councils to establish 
 offices and regulate salaries, is better than either of the other 
 laws. 
 
 Municipal ownership is authorized for waterworks, gas- 
 works, electric light works, and heating and power plants, 
 after a referendum vote. But the debt limit of two per cent 
 of the taxable value is likely to prevent most cities from 
 undertaking all these functions. 
 
 All franchises previously granted are legalized; and au- 
 thority is given to grant new franchises, with no statutory 
 restriction as to the term of the grant, while contracts for a 
 supply of light, water, or heat for city purposes may be made 
 for periods of twenty-five years. In these respects the new 
 law shows a distinct reactionary movement in the interest 
 of private corporations. Formerly franchises were limited 
 to periods of ten and thirty-four years, according to the kind, 
 and contracts for light were limited to ten years. 
 
 No simple verdict can be given on the act as a whole. The 
 relaxation of the restrictions on franchise corporations is 
 likely to prove a serious evil. The prohibition on the reelec- 
 tion of members of the council will promote unnecessary 
 changes in public policy. The opportunity to introduce 
 other improvements has been neglected, and the act is far 
 from perfect in respect to the arrangement of its various parts. 
 
 On the other hand, so far as concerns the organization of 
 the municipal government, the measure is a decided advance 
 on previous conditions in Indiana and a still greater improve- 
 ment on existing conditions in other states. It is of no little 
 advantage to have the law on this subject reduced to simpler 
 and more systematic terms. This should reduce the amount 
 of litigation in the courts and make the municipal system 
 one that can be generally understood by the people. The
 
 124 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 centralization of executive powers and responsibility in the 
 mayor should clarify the situation for the voters on election 
 day, and the opportunity given by the law for the establish- 
 ment of the merit system in the municipal service is at least 
 a step in the right direction.
 
 VII 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 1 
 
 CONSIDERING the amount of published discussion on munici- 
 pal government in the United States, it is somewhat sur- 
 prising that there should be a lack of definite information 
 concerning the primary facts of municipal organization. 
 Most of the literature, however, which deals with the structure 
 of municipal government is devoted to advocacy of proposed 
 changes; and references to existing conditions are either 
 confessedly limited to a few cities, or are vague statements, 
 often erroneous because made without the detailed investi- 
 gation which must be the foundation of any safe generaliza- 
 tion. Yet it would seem that the task of securing a satis- 
 factory system of municipal organization would be aided 
 by a comprehensive examination of existing methods; and 
 that it would be worth while for students of this problem 
 to understand with some degree of exactness what are the 
 leading practices and prevailing tendencies of the time. 
 
 It is in this belief, and as a first step in this direction, that 
 this paper has been prepared. Much of the information has 
 been secured by a series of inquiries addressed to the cities 
 which, according to the census of 1900, have a population of 
 more than 25,000. The facts thus collected have been sup- 
 plemented by other data from various sources. The study 
 deals for the most part with the structural organization of 
 municipal councils. Some remarks are added in reference to 
 the general character of the powers conferred on these bodies ; 
 but there is no attempt to analyze the minutely enumerated 
 "powers" which are in fact rather limitations which 
 form so large a part of most municipal charters. 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Political Science Quarterly, XIX, 234 (June, 
 1904). 
 
 125
 
 126 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ORGANIZATION 
 
 Number of Chambers. In the early days American city 
 councils were always single bodies, like the town councils in 
 England after which they were modelled. During the nine- 
 teenth century the bicameral system was introduced in many 
 cities, sometimes in imitation of the bicameral state legis- 
 latures and the national Congress, but in Massachusetts as a 
 development from the town-meeting government. At one 
 time or another most of the large cities have had a bicameral 
 council; and, while many of them have returned to the single- 
 house system, two councils are still found in Philadelphia, 
 St. Louis, Boston, Baltimore, Buffalo, and Pittsburg one- 
 half of the cities with over 300,000 population. Apart from 
 the large cities, the bicameral system is now almost confined 
 to New England, Pennsylvania, Virginia, and Kentucky; 
 but there are a few other sporadic cases, as in St. Paul, At- 
 lanta, Wheeling, Mobile, and Chattanooga. In the United 
 States as a whole, about one-third of the cities of over 25,000 
 population have the bicameral system. In the smaller cities 
 the proportion is less: in 1892, out of 376 cities with over 
 8000 inhabitants, only 82 had a bicameral council. The 
 single-chamber council, which has always been the more 
 prevalent form, 1 is found, among the large cities, in New 
 York, Chicago, Cleveland, Cincinnati, San Francisco, New 
 Orleans, Detroit, and Milwaukee. 
 
 In some cities which have nominally only a single council 
 there is another body, which, although ostensibly only an 
 executive authority, has some resemblance to a second 
 branch of the council. Such bodies are the boards of esti- 
 mates in New York City and in the four cities of the second 
 class in New York State, and the boards of public service 
 in Ohio cities. 
 
 Number of Members. In this respect there is naturally 
 
 1 Mr. Bryce's statement (American Commonwealth, ch. 50) that the 
 bicameral system is the more common must have been based on limited 
 investigation, confined to the larger cities of the Eastern states.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 127 
 
 a wide difference between large and small cities ; but there is 
 seldom any definite relation between the size of a city and 
 the size of its council. For the most part the councils are 
 smaller than in European cities. Philadelphia, with 41 
 members in the select council and 149 in the common council, 
 has by far the largest membership. Next to this come Bos- 
 ton with 88 members in two councils, New York with 79 
 members, and Chicago with 70, in a single chamber. There 
 are few other cities with more than forty members, and by far 
 the larger number have less than thirty. In New England 
 cities the councils are usually larger in proportion to the 
 population than in other parts of the country. Some cities 
 have strikingly small councils. San Francisco has only 
 eighteen members, New Orleans only seventeen, and the 
 cities of Iowa from six to ten. In Memphis the council con- 
 sists of the board of fire and police commissioners and the 
 board of public works, meeting as one body of eleven mem- 
 bers. In Galveston the powers of a council are exercised by 
 a board of four commissioners. 1 
 
 Term of Service. The term of service in municipal coun- 
 cils varies from one to four years in different cities; but the 
 prevailing period is clearly two years. In New England 
 .annual elections for the whole membership of the council are 
 still almost universal. Elsewhere biennial terms are to be 
 found with few exceptions; but in many places one-half of 
 the members are chosen each alternate year, so that there is 
 a municipal election every year. The most important in- 
 stances of longer terms may be noted. In Philadelphia, 
 while the members of the common council serve for two 
 years, those in the select council are chosen for three years. 
 ,So, too, in St. Louis and Buffalo, while the larger chambers 
 of the councils have a two-year term, the members of the 
 smaller chambers are elected for four years. A three-year 
 
 1 As first established, two commissioners were appointed by the Gov- 
 ernor and two elected. All are now elected. Similar arrangements 
 tave been established in Houston, and laws have been passed in Kansas 
 and Iowa (1907) authorizing a like plan.
 
 128 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 term is also found in Mobile for both branches of the council ; 
 and a four-year term in Memphis, Evansville, Charleston, 
 Birmingham, Sacramento, and La Crosse. 
 
 These short terms for members of city councils are not 
 offset by any strong tendency to continuous reelection; 
 and, as a result of the almost complete changes which take 
 place, generally within two years, there is little opportunity 
 for members of the councils to acquire experience in munici- 
 pal affairs. Specific information about the length of service 
 is difficult to obtain; but the following data for a few cities 
 will illustrate the general statement. From 1836 to 1900 
 there had been in Newark, N. J., a total of 569 aldermen. 
 Of these, 342, about 60 per cent, had held the position for 
 two years or less; 49 had served for three years, and 117 for 
 four years. Only 61, or a little over ten per cent, had served 
 for more than four years; and 40 of these had only one or 
 two years additional. Of the remaining 21, 17 were aldermen 
 from seven to ten years; and the four holding records for 
 longest service held the positions for 13, 14, 16, and 22 years 
 respectively. 1 The St. Louis house of delegates for 1899- 
 1901 had among its 28 members but eight who had served 
 in the previous house, and only two who had a longer term 
 of service. One of these two, however, had been a member 
 of the house for 14 years. 2 The Cincinnati board of legisla- 
 tion in 1900, out of 31 members, had four who were also on 
 the board in 1895. The Cleveland council of 1901-02 had 
 not a single member who was on the council in 1895. 
 
 The Chicago council in recent years shows a larger pro- 
 portion of reelections. Of the 35 members whose terms 
 expired in the spring of 1902, 22 (nearly two-thirds) were 
 reflected. Seven had served for six years, four for eight 
 years, and one member has been in the council for 14 years. 
 At the council election in Detroit in 1901, seven of the 17 
 members chosen were reflected. 
 
 1 Compiled from Common Council Manual for Newark, 1900, pp. 
 148-155. 
 
 2 Municipal Code of St. Louis, 1900, pp. 1011-1026.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 129 
 
 Mode of Election. Members are for the most part chosen 
 by wards or districts. This system is almost universal for 
 single-chambered councils and for the larger house in bi- 
 cameral councils. Most often each district chooses one or 
 two members. The number of cities having one member 
 from each district and the number having two are nearly the 
 same ; but in the large cities the one-member district is more 
 general, this plan being followed in New York, St. Louis, 
 Baltimore, Buffalo, Cleveland, and Cincinnati, while the two- 
 member plan is followed in Chicago and Detroit. Boston 
 and many other New England cities have three members 
 from each ward ; while a few cities in New England and Penn- 
 sylvania (Philadelphia, Pittsburg, and Allegheny) have a 
 variable number presumably in proportion to the popula- 
 tion of the various districts. 
 
 It has often been urged that this district system constitutes 
 one of the main factors in the election of inferior and dishonest 
 members of municipal councils. It is contended that at 
 best it lends itself to the election of members who will pay 
 more attention to the needs of their districts than to the larger 
 interests of the city as a whole; and that the concentration 
 of the worst elements of the city's population in some wards 
 makes inevitable the election of a number of very objection- 
 able members. Moreover the ward lines seldom mark off 
 any natural divisions of the city, with a developed local senti- 
 ment and opinion; and the making and changing of ward 
 boundaries lends itself to artificial gerrymandering for par- 
 tisan purposes. Even without deliberate gerrymandering, 
 it is quite possible, under the district system, for a minority 
 of the voters to elect a majority of the council; or for a 
 comparatively small majority to elect practically the whole 
 council. 
 
 In rapidly growing cities other difficulties are introduced. 
 The increase in population is not spread uniformly over the 
 whole city, but is concentrated in certain districts, while 
 at the same time there is a decrease of residents in the busi-
 
 130 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ness sections ; and it is thus almost impossible, if the prevail- 
 ing system of equal representation in each ward is maintained, 
 to adhere even approximately to the theory of representation 
 in proportion to population. The subjoined table demon- 
 strates this inequality for a number of the larger cities ; 1 and 
 similar if less striking figures might be given for the smaller 
 cities. It is, moreover, of special significance that, in the 
 largest cities at least, the districts with relatively small and 
 decreasing population, which thus have an excessive repre- 
 sentation in the councils, are often districts where the worst 
 elements of the population are to be found. If the districts 
 were of equal area, the congestion in the slum districts would 
 give the opposite effect ; but the small area of the slum wards, 
 and the tendency of population there to decrease as the busi- 
 ness sections develop, bring about this over-representation 
 of such wards. Thus in New York the Battery district is 
 the smallest ; and in Chicago, before the recent re-districting, 
 the first ward was one of the smallest. 
 
 Some exceptions to the prevailing system of district repre- 
 sentation should be noted. Where the single-chamber coun- 
 cil exists, the most general of these exceptions is the election, 
 
 1 MUNICIPAL WARD AND DISTRICT POPULATIONS, 1900. 
 
 
 MOST 
 POPULOUS 
 DISTRICT. 
 
 LEAST 
 POPULOUS 
 DISTRICT. 
 
 AVERAGE 
 DISTRICT 
 POPULA- 
 TION. 
 
 No. 
 DIST- 
 RICTS 
 
 No. 20% 
 
 OVER 
 
 AVER- 
 AGE. 
 
 No. 20% 
 
 UNDEB 
 
 AVER- 
 AGE. 
 
 New York * .... 
 Chicago .... 
 Philadelphia . . . 
 Boston 
 
 122,395 
 106,124 
 65,372 
 32,566 
 
 25,959 
 11,795 
 6,953 
 12,840 
 
 60,000 
 49,000 
 32,000 
 22 000 
 
 35 
 35 
 41 
 25 
 
 10 
 10 
 14 
 5 
 
 14 
 17 
 17 
 3 
 
 St. Louis .... 
 Baltimore .... 
 Cleveland .... 
 Buffalo 
 
 27,998 
 24,117 
 60,504 
 29,414 
 
 12,212 
 19,201 
 17,679 
 
 6,488 
 
 20,000 
 21,000 
 34,700 
 14 000 
 
 28 
 24 
 11 
 25 
 
 5 
 
 4 
 6 
 
 3 
 
 4 
 13 
 
 San Francisco . 
 Cincinnati .... 
 Pittsburg .... 
 New Orleans . . . 
 Detroit 
 
 27,836 
 15,995 
 22,669 
 31,663 
 
 28,281 
 
 12,797 
 3,763 
 660 
 4,484 
 9,313 
 
 19,000 
 10,000 
 8,500 
 17,000 
 17,000 
 
 18 
 31 
 38 
 17 
 17 
 
 4 
 11 
 12 
 6 
 2 
 
 2 
 6 
 20 
 5 
 3 
 
 Milwaukee .... 
 
 21,903 
 
 5,418 
 
 13,500 
 
 21 
 
 8 
 
 6 
 
 * Manhattan and Bronx.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 131 
 
 in addition to the ward representatives, of a small number 
 of members from the city at large. This plan is followed 
 regularly in Indiana and Iowa, has been adopted in the new 
 Ohio code, and is found in a few other sporadic cases. 1 In 
 a few cases all of the members are elected at large, as in the 
 board of supervisors which takes the place of the council in 
 San Francisco, and the boards which act as the council in 
 Memphis. 2 More frequently, the smaller body in a bicameral 
 council is elected from the whole city instead of by wards; 
 indeed, for these bodies the general ticket system is almost as 
 common as the district system. This general ticket system 
 is followed in St. Louis, Buffalo, Louisville, St. Paul, and 
 commonly in Massachusetts and Kentucky. But in Boston 
 the aldermen have been chosen by districts ; and in the Penn- 
 sylvania cities select councils are elected by wards, each 
 ward having one member in these bodies, irrespective of 
 population, while in the common councils the representation 
 of wards is apportioned on the basis of population. 
 
 Minority Representation. Under a general ticket system 
 of voting, one party is almost certain to elect all of the mem- 
 bers chosen at one election, and a large minority of voters - 
 or even a majority, if the election is decided by a plurality 
 may have no representation in the council. To obviate such 
 a result, various schemes of voting have been devised; and 
 several of them have been put in operation, but only in a 
 few places, and usually to be abandoned after a few years. 
 In New York City an elected board of ten governors for the 
 almshouse was established in 1849, two to be chosen each 
 year. Each voter had but one vote, and the two candidates 
 who received the largest number of votes were elected. In 
 1857 a board of supervisors for New York County was estab- 
 lished to be chosen on a similar plan. Each voter could vote 
 for but six of the twelve members to be chosen; the six can- 
 
 1 San Antonio, Dallas, and Montgomery. 
 
 2 Also the boards of commissioners under the recent Texas, Kansas, 
 and Iowa laws.
 
 132 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 didates receiving the largest vote were declared elected, and 
 the six candidates next in the order of their vote were to 
 be appointed by the board. These methods gave the prin- 
 cipal minority party equal representation with the party 
 casting the largest vote. 
 
 A slightly different method was followed for the New York 
 board of education in 1869, when there were seven elected 
 members and five appointed from the candidates next in 
 number of votes to those elected. From 1873 to 1882 a 
 similar system of minority representation was in operation 
 in New York City for the election of the municipal council. 
 Six aldermen were chosen at large, but no elector could vote 
 for more than four; the remainder were elected in five dis- 
 tricts, each choosing three members, but no elector could 
 vote for more than two. 1 Some time after these experi- 
 ments had been abandoned in New York, the same principle 
 of limited voting was applied in Boston, in 1893, for the board 
 of aldermen the smaller branch of the city council. The 
 twelve aldermen were elected at large ; but no elector could 
 vote for more than seven. After a few years this arrange- 
 ment was abandoned, but a somewhat similar plan went into 
 operation in the fall of 1903. A slightly different plan, 
 which secures much the same results, has been used for the 
 election of the board of sanitary trustees in Chicago. Each 
 voter had nine votes the same number as the number of 
 members on the board and these votes might be given 
 one to each of nine candidates, or they might be distributed 
 among not less than five candidates. 
 
 These plans of limited voting insure a certain kind of 
 
 1 Political Science Quarterly, XIV, 691. Under this system not 
 only were a considerable number of Republican members elected, but 
 the different factions of the Democratic party were also represented. 
 The change to the single-member system was made without discussion 
 or popular demand, and there seems reason to think that it was made 
 in the interest of uniting the Democratic factions under one control. 
 It is perhaps significant that within two years after the system of minor- 
 ity representation was abandoned a board of aldermen was elected which 
 became notorious for the bribery of its members.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 133 
 
 minority representation; and some of the earlier plans gave 
 a larger representation to minorities than they could justly 
 claim on the principle of majority rule. But all of these 
 devices are open to serious objections. On the one hand, 
 the courts have held, in some states, that where an elector 
 is not permitted to vote for the full number of persons to be 
 elected, he is deprived of his constitutional rights. On the 
 other hand, these plans have been criticised from the point 
 of view of public policy. Resting as they do on the assump- 
 tion that the voters are permanently divided into two organ- 
 ized parties, they tend to promote the conduct and control 
 of municipal elections by the national party organizations. 
 This reduces the influence of independent voters. Even 
 where such voters hold the balance of power, they can control 
 the election only of one or two members; and in most cases 
 a nomination by either of the principal parties has proved 
 to be almost equivalent to an election. 
 
 Other plans of minority and proportional representation 
 have been proposed and discussed; but none except those 
 described above have as yet been put in operation in munici- 
 pal elections in this country. Among the plans proposed 
 is that of cumulative voting, which has been employed with 
 considerable satisfaction in Illinois since 1870, for electing 
 members of the state House of Representatives. 1 
 
 Compensation. Some financial compensation or salary 
 is paid to members of municipal councils in nearly all of the 
 large cities, and in the majority of the smaller cities. The 
 largest salary, $2000 a year, is paid to the New York alder- 
 men. The members of the Chicago council and of the Boston 
 board of aldermen have each $1500. The annual stipend 
 is $1200 in San Francisco, Detroit, and Los Angeles; and 
 $1000 in Baltimore, Buffalo, and Denver. In other cities 
 
 1 Cumulative voting has been held to be unconstitutional in Michigan 
 (84 Michigan, 228); and probably in most states an amendment to the 
 state constitution would be necessary before it could be legally estab- 
 lished.
 
 134 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the amount is usually between $200 and $400, or, in smaller 
 places, from $2 to $5 per meeting. Even in the St. Louis 
 assembly and in the Boston common council the members 
 receive only $300 a year. Where the compensation is a 
 fixed amount per meeting the payment is often dependent 
 upon attendance; and in other cases there is a reduction 
 in salary or a fine imposed for absence. In some cases the presi- 
 dent of the council receives a larger salary than the other mem- 
 bers; and in New York City this official is paid $5000 a year. 
 
 In many cities, however, the older rule of no salaries to 
 members of municipal councils is still followed. This is 
 almost the universal rule in New England (except in Boston) 
 and in Pennsylvania; it obtains frequently in New Jersey 
 and in the Southern states, and occasionally in other states. 1 
 The largest cities where no salaries are paid are Philadelphia, 
 Pittsburg, Newark, Jersey City, and Louisville. 
 
 Standing of Councillors. The inferior business standing 
 and character of persons elected to large American city councils 
 has been a frequent subject of remark, but there have been 
 few attempts to study this point in detail. In 1895 Mayor 
 Matthews, of Boston, collected some definite facts on this 
 point for the city of Boston. He presented statistics showing 
 that, during the first fifty years after the creation of the city 
 government in 1822, from 85 to 95 per cent of the members 
 of the council were owners of property assessed for taxation; 
 but that after 1875 the proportion had rapidly declined, and 
 in 1895 less than 30 per cent of the council members were prop- 
 erty owners. Not only had the percentage of property owners 
 declined, but the total assessed value of property owned 
 by council members, which had been $986,400 in 1822, and 
 $2,300,400 in 1875, had fallen to $372,000 in 1894. Mr, 
 Matthews' statistics are reproduced in the following table : 
 
 1 In the states of the Middle West the only instance among cities 
 of over 25,000 appears to be Oshkosh, Wis.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 
 
 135 
 
 PROPERTY INTERESTS OF MEMBERS OF THE BOSTON 
 CITY COUNCIL 1 
 
 BOARD OP ALDERMEN 
 
 YEAH. 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 No. AS- 
 SESSED 
 
 PER CENT 
 
 OF MEMBERS 
 ASSESSED 
 
 AMOUNTS 
 ASSESSED TO 
 MEMBERS 
 
 TOTAL ASSESSED 
 VALUATION OF 
 
 CITY 
 
 PERCENTAGE OF 
 TOTAL VALUA- 
 TION ASSESSED 
 TO MEMBERS 
 
 1822 
 
 8 
 
 8 
 
 100.00 
 
 $146,100 
 
 $42,140,200 
 
 .00347 
 
 1830 
 
 8 
 
 8 
 
 100.00 
 
 99,400 
 
 59,586,000 
 
 .00167 
 
 1840 
 
 8 
 
 8 
 
 100.00 
 
 168,800 
 
 94,581,600 
 
 .00178 
 
 1850 
 
 8 
 
 8 
 
 100.00 
 
 261,800 
 
 180,000,500 
 
 .00145 
 
 1860 
 
 12 
 
 12 
 
 100.00 
 
 622,900 
 
 276,861,000 
 
 .00225 
 
 1870 
 
 12 
 
 12 
 
 100.00 
 
 476,200 
 
 584,089,400 
 
 .00081 
 
 1875 
 
 12 
 
 12 
 
 100.00 
 
 769,600 
 
 793,961,895 
 
 .00097 
 
 1880 
 
 13 
 
 11 
 
 84.61 
 
 197,900 
 
 639,462,495 
 
 .00031 
 
 1885 
 
 12 
 
 7 
 
 58.33 
 
 457,900 
 
 685,579,072 
 
 .00067 
 
 1890 
 
 12 
 
 8 
 
 66.66 
 
 206,200 
 
 822,041,800 
 
 .00025 
 
 1895 
 
 12 
 
 9 
 
 75.00 
 
 105,500 
 
 928,109,042 
 
 .00013 
 
 COMMON COUNCIL 
 
 1822 
 
 48 
 
 45 
 
 93.75 
 
 840,300 
 
 42,140,200 
 
 .01994 
 
 1830 
 
 49 
 
 38 
 
 77.55 
 
 228,300 
 
 59,586,000 
 
 .00383 
 
 1840 
 
 48 
 
 40 
 
 83.33 
 
 204,400 
 
 94,581,600 
 
 .00216 
 
 1850 
 
 48 
 
 36 
 
 75.00 
 
 225,850 
 
 180,000,500 
 
 .00125 
 
 1860 
 
 48 
 
 41 
 
 85.41 
 
 1,116,400 
 
 276,861,000 
 
 .00403 
 
 1870 
 
 64 
 
 56 
 
 87.50 
 
 1,050,900 
 
 584,089,400 
 
 .00180 
 
 1875 
 
 74 
 
 61 
 
 82.43 
 
 1,530,800 
 
 793,961,895 
 
 .00192 
 
 1880 
 
 75 
 
 42 
 
 56.00 
 
 667,000 
 
 639,462,495 
 
 .00143 
 
 1885 
 
 72 
 
 29 
 
 40.55 
 
 290,300 
 
 685,579,072 
 
 .00042 
 
 1890 
 
 73 
 
 20 
 
 27.39 
 
 315,700 
 
 822,041,800 
 
 .00038 
 
 1895 
 
 75 
 
 16 
 
 20.33 
 
 266,500 
 
 928,109,042 
 
 .00029 
 
 Meetings. Regular meetings of councils in large American 
 cities are usually held on a fixed evening in each week; in 
 less important cities, including, however, such places as 
 Milwaukee and Toledo, once a fortnight; and in the smaller 
 cities often not more than once a month. In small cities 
 and also in some important cities, as Chicago, Providence, and 
 Grand Rapids, the mayor presides; but in most large cities there 
 is usually a president of the council, sometimes chosen by the 
 council, sometimes elected as a councilman for the whole city. 
 
 Committees. As in Congress and the state legislatures, 
 much of the effective work of municipal councils is performed 
 1 N. Matthews, City Government of Boston, p. 171.
 
 136 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 by standing committees. In most large cities there are from 
 fifteen to twenty-five regular committees, appointed for dif- 
 ferent branches of municipal administration. Some cities 
 with bicameral councils provide for joint committees of the 
 two chambers, and in this way reduce the chances for a dead- 
 lock. The number of committees and the subjects referred 
 to each vary from time to time in each city. 1 These com- 
 mittees have normally from three to seven members. They 
 hold meetings at irregular intervals, according to the busi- 
 ness before them. In small cities they have often direct 
 supervision over the technical agents and the employees of 
 the city in their respective branches of administration; and 
 often, while special administrative officers or boards have 
 been created for some department in a given city, other 
 departments remain under the immediate control of council 
 committees. 
 
 POWERS 
 
 It would serve little purpose to examine the host of detailed 
 powers granted to city councils under the system of special 
 legislation, enumerated powers, and strict construction which 
 prevails in all of the states. But a few remarks may be 
 made about each of the two primary divisions, into which 
 these powers may be classified: the control over administra- 
 tive officers, and the power of enacting ordinances. 
 
 Control over Administration. While both Congress and 
 the state legislatures have and exercise large powers in the 
 creation of administrative offices, municipal councils in most 
 states have very limited powers in this direction. The general 
 situation on this point has been well summarized by Judge 
 Dillon : 
 
 1 Detroit has at present the following list: Ways and means, claims 
 and accounts, judiciary, franchises, grade separation, streets, fire limits, 
 house of correction, public buildings, sewers, taxes, street openings, 
 printing, markets, public lighting, parks and boulevards, ordinances, 
 pounds, health, licenses, city hospitals, liquor bonds, rules, charter and 
 city legislation, and bridges.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 137 
 
 The charter or constitution of the corporation usually provides with 
 care as to all the principal officers, such as mayor, aldermen, marshal, 
 clerk, treasurer, and the like, and prescribes their general duties. This 
 leaves but little necessity or room for the exercise of any implied power 
 to create other offices and appoint other officers. It is supposed, how- 
 ever, when not in contravention of the charter, that municipal corpo- 
 rations may to a limited extent have as incidental to express powers the 
 right to create certain minor offices of a ministerial or executive nature. 
 Thus, if power be conferred to provide for the health of the inhab- 
 itants, this would give the corporation the right to pass ordinances to 
 secure this end, and the execution of such ordinance might be commit- 
 ted to a health officer, although no such officer be specifically named hi 
 the organic act, if this course would not conflict with any of its pro- 
 visions. But the power to create offices even of this character would 
 be limited to such as the nature of the duties devolved by charter or 
 statute on the corporation naturally and reasonably require. 1 
 
 The general law governing municipal corporations in Illi- 
 nois gives the city councils in that state a much larger field 
 for the creation of local offices than is usually possessed. 
 This statute provides only for a city council, mayor, clerk, 
 attorney, and treasurer, and then authorizes the council by 
 a two-thirds vote to establish such other offices as it deems 
 necessary and to discontinue any of these offices by a like 
 vote. In the words of the statute: 
 
 The city council may in its discretion, from time to time, by ordi- 
 nance passed by a vote of two-thirds of all the aldermen elected, 
 provide for the election by the legal voters of the city or the appoint- 
 ment by the mayor with the approval of the city council of a city 
 collector, a city marshal, a city superintendent of streets, a corporation 
 counsel, a city comptroller, or any or either of them, and such other 
 officers as may by said council be deemed necessary or expedient. 
 The city council may by a like vote, by ordinance or resolution, to 
 take effect at the end of their fiscal year, discontinue any office so 
 created and devolve the duties thereof on any other officer. 2 
 
 In many cities the councils retain a considerable power of 
 appointment to municipal offices. The position of city clerk 
 
 1 Dillon, Municipal Corporations, 207. 
 
 2 Revised Statutes of Illinois, 1899, ch. 24, 73.
 
 138 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 is more frequently filled by council appointment than in any 
 other way. 1 Less frequently the councils elect to other 
 offices, and sometimes fill all important positions. This 
 large appointing power is found in Minneapolis, Providence, 
 generally in New England (except Boston and Connecticut 
 cities), and Pennsylvania (except the four largest cities), and 
 in some smaller cities, as St. Joseph, Birmingham, Mont- 
 gomery, and Fort Worth. More often, however, offices other 
 than that of city clerk are filled by election, or by the nomi- 
 nation of the mayor, subject to confirmation of the council. 
 In some cities this power of the council to confirm is used by 
 individual members of the council to dictate nominations; 
 but in other cities, as in Chicago and Cleveland, the mayor's 
 nominations are regularly confirmed. In a number of larger 
 cities, even the power of confirmation has been taken away; 
 but this development might more properly be noted in a 
 study of the powers of the mayor. 
 
 The council has nearly always the right to receive reports 
 from the various municipal departments, and to investigate 
 the work of the departments by means of its committees. 
 The control exercised in this way is made effective by the 
 power of the council over the finances, and especially by 
 its authority over appropriations. It has often happened, 
 however, that this power has been used, not to limit, but to 
 increase the expenditures, and in such a way as to help the 
 aldermen's political prospects rather than for the best inter- 
 ests of the city. In consequence of this, in some important 
 cities the financial powers of the councils have been very 
 materially limited. In the principal cities of New York 
 State the councils cannot increase the appropriations above 
 the sums placed in the budget by the board of estimates 
 a device similar to that followed voluntarily by the British 
 House of Commons. In Chicago, on the other hand, the 
 
 1 The council does not select this officer in Chicago, St. Louis, San 
 Francisco, Detroit, or Indianapolis, nor generally in the cities of Illinois, 
 Indiana, Michigan, Wisconsin, Kentucky, and Missouri.
 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 139 
 
 finance committee of the city council has a large influence in 
 determining the appropriations. 
 
 Ordinance Power. Judicial decisions have laid down 
 certain general principles which govern and limit the ordi- 
 nance power of municipal councils. Municipal ordinances 
 must be reasonable and lawful; they must not be oppressive 
 in character; they must be impartial, fair, and general in 
 their application; and they must be consistent with the 
 public policy of the state as declared in general legislation. 
 
 The output of city ordinances generally varies with the size 
 of the city; and in the large cities the enormous total is far 
 beyond the power of any individual to comprehend. The 
 New York ordinances make a comparatively small volume 
 of 250 pages; but this is because so much that elsewhere is 
 done by council ordinance is done for New York by legisla- 
 tive enactments and is found in the city charter, while many 
 ordinances are established by the police, health, and other 
 administrative departments. The Chicago ordinances are 
 in two thick volumes of 1000 pages each; those of St. Louis 
 cover more than 500 large pages of fine print; small cities 
 usually have all their ordinances in a pamphlet of perhaps not 
 more than 100 pages. 
 
 In most cases this mass of municipal law is printed without 
 any attempt at systematic classification. A frequent method 
 is to arrange the ordinances by subjects, in alphabetical order. 
 The city of Nashville, however, commendably publishes its 
 ordinances according to a definite system which groups to- 
 gether those covering related subjects. The first part pre- 
 sents the ordinances relating to the election and appointment 
 of municipal officers. The second part gives the ordinances 
 governing the duties of the various municipal departments. 
 The third part has the police regulations affecting the general 
 public, in two divisions: one containing the ordinances to 
 secure order, decency, and good morals; the other, the ordi- 
 nances for public convenience and safety. The fourth part 
 includes the ordinances on financial affairs, including the
 
 140 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 permanent tax laws, the annual budget, and ordinances pro- 
 viding for bond issues. The fifth part gives the munici- 
 pal and ward boundaries. In an appendix are collected 
 the grants and franchises to railroads, lighting plants, tele- 
 graph and telephone companies, and other special privileges. 
 
 STATISTICS 
 
 Tabulated statistics are presented below, showing the or- 
 ganization of the municipal councils in nearly all the American 
 cities which, according to the census of 1900, had a population 
 of 25,000 or more. 
 
 STATISTICS OF AMERICAN CITY COUNCILS, 1903 
 
 
 SINGLE OR LARGER HOUSE 
 
 SMALLER HOUSE 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 (') 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 () 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 (') 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 
 New York 
 
 79 
 
 73 + 6 
 
 2 
 
 $2000 
 
 
 
 
 
 Chicago 
 
 70 
 
 2X35 
 
 2 
 
 1500 
 
 
 
 
 
 Philadelphia 
 
 149 
 
 nX41 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 41 
 
 1X41 
 
 3 
 
 none 
 
 St. Louis 
 
 28 
 
 1X28 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 13 
 
 A.L. 
 
 4 
 
 $300 
 
 Boston 
 
 75 
 
 3X25 
 
 1 
 
 300 
 
 13 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 1500 
 
 Baltimore 
 
 24 
 
 1X24 
 
 2 
 
 1000 
 
 8 
 
 
 2 
 
 1000 
 
 Cleveland 
 
 33 
 
 27 + 6 
 
 2 
 
 600 
 
 
 
 
 
 Buffalo 
 
 25 
 
 1X25 
 
 2 
 
 1000 
 
 9 
 
 A.L. 
 
 4 
 
 1000 
 
 San Francisco 
 
 18 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 1200 
 
 
 
 
 
 Cincinnati 
 
 32 
 
 26 + 6 
 
 2 
 
 1200 
 
 
 
 
 
 New Orleans 
 
 17 
 
 1X17 
 
 4 
 
 240 
 
 
 
 
 
 Pittsburg 
 
 51 
 
 nX38 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 38 
 
 1X38 
 
 4 
 
 none 
 
 Detroit 
 
 34 
 
 2X17 
 
 2 
 
 1200 
 
 
 
 
 
 Milwaukee 
 
 46 
 
 2X23 
 
 2 
 
 400 
 
 
 
 
 
 Washington 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Newark 
 
 30 
 
 2X15 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Jersey City 
 
 25 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Louisville 
 
 24 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 
 12 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 
 Minneapolis 
 
 26 
 
 2X13 
 
 4 
 
 500 
 
 
 
 
 
 Providence 4 
 
 40 
 
 4X10 
 
 1 
 
 300 
 
 10 
 
 X 
 
 1 
 
 500 
 
 Indianapolis 
 
 21 
 
 15 + 6 
 
 5 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Kansas City 
 
 14 
 
 1X14 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 14 
 
 A.L. 
 
 4 
 
 300 
 
 St. Paul 
 
 11 
 
 ixn 
 
 2 
 
 100 
 
 9 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 100 
 
 Rochester 
 
 20 
 
 1X20 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Denver 
 
 16 
 
 1X16 
 
 2 
 
 1000 
 
 
 
 
 
 Toledo 
 
 16 
 
 13 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Allegheny 
 
 40 
 
 nXl5 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 15 
 
 
 4 
 
 none 
 
 Columbus, O. 
 
 15 
 
 12 + 3 - 
 
 2 
 
 442 
 
 
 
 
 
 Worcester 
 
 24 
 
 3X8 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 9 
 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 Syracuse 
 
 19 
 
 1X19 
 
 2 
 
 200 
 
 
 
 
 
 New Haven 
 
 45 
 
 3X15 
 
 2 
 
 
 30 
 
 
 2 

 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 141 
 
 STATISTICS OF AMERICAN CITY COUNCILS (Continued) 
 
 
 SINGLE OB LARGER HOUSE 
 
 SMALLER HOUSE 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 C) 
 
 No. or 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 0) 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 C) 
 
 Paterson 
 
 22 
 
 X8 
 
 2 
 
 $400 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fall River 
 
 27 
 
 18+9 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 St. Joseph 
 
 15 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 200 
 
 9 
 
 
 2 
 
 $200 
 
 Omaha 
 
 9 
 
 
 3 
 
 900 
 
 
 
 
 
 Los Angeles 
 Memphis 5 
 
 9 
 11 
 
 1X9 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 4 
 
 1200 
 120 
 
 
 
 
 
 Scran ton 
 
 
 X21 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Lowell 
 
 27 
 
 3X9 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 9 
 
 A.L. 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 Albany 
 
 19 
 
 1X19 
 
 2 
 
 500 
 
 
 
 
 
 Cambridge 
 
 22 
 
 2X11 
 
 1 
 
 
 11 
 
 A.L. 
 
 1 
 
 
 Portland, Or. 
 
 11 
 
 ixii 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Atlanta 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 7 
 
 1X7 
 
 3 
 
 300 
 
 Grand Rapids 
 
 24 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 350 
 
 
 
 
 
 Dayton 
 
 13 
 
 10 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 350 
 
 
 
 
 
 Richmond 
 
 35 
 
 nx6 
 
 2 
 
 
 21 
 
 
 2 
 
 
 Nashville 
 
 20 
 
 1X20 
 
 2 
 
 5() 
 
 
 
 
 
 Seattle 
 
 13 
 
 9 + 4 
 
 3-4 
 
 900 
 
 
 
 
 
 Hartford 
 
 40 
 
 4X10 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 20 
 
 X 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 Reading 
 
 16 
 
 1X16 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Wilmington, Del. 
 
 13 
 
 
 2 
 
 240 
 
 
 
 
 
 Camden, N.J. 
 
 25 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Trenton, N.J. 
 
 28 
 
 2X14 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Bridgeport, Conn. 
 
 24 
 
 1X24 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Lynn, Mass. 
 
 25 
 
 nX7 
 
 1 
 
 
 11 
 
 A.L. 
 
 1 
 
 300 
 
 Oakland, Cal. 
 
 11 
 
 ? 
 
 2 
 
 480 
 
 
 
 
 
 Lawrence, Mass. 
 
 18 
 
 3X6 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 6 
 
 1X6 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 New Bedford, Mass. 
 
 24 
 
 4X6 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 6 
 
 
 1 
 
 100 
 
 Des Moines, la. 
 
 9 
 
 7 + 2 
 
 2 
 
 250 
 
 
 
 
 
 Springfield, Mass. 
 
 18 
 
 nx8 
 
 2 
 
 
 8 
 
 
 2 
 
 
 Somerville, Mass. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 7 
 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 Troy, N.Y. 
 
 17 
 
 1X17 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Hoboken, N.J. 
 
 10 
 
 2X5 
 
 2 
 
 400 
 
 
 
 
 
 Evansville, Ind. 
 
 11 
 
 7 + 4 
 
 4 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Manchester, N.H. 
 
 30 
 
 3X10 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 10 
 
 X 
 
 2 
 
 3(") 
 
 Utica, N.Y. 
 
 15 
 
 1X15 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Peoria, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 3(") 
 
 
 
 
 
 Charleston, S.C. 
 
 24 
 
 12 + 12 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Savannah, Ga. 
 
 12 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Salt Lake City 
 
 15 
 
 3X5 
 
 2 
 
 420 
 
 
 
 
 
 San Antonio, Tex. 
 
 12 
 
 8 + 4 
 
 2 
 
 6() 
 
 
 
 
 
 Duluth, Minn. 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Erie, Pa. 
 
 12 
 
 2X6 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Elizabeth, N.J. 
 
 24 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 Wilkesbarre, Pa. 
 
 16 
 
 1X16 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Kansas City, Kan. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Harrisburg, Pa. 
 
 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Portland, Me. 
 
 27 
 
 3X9 
 
 1 
 
 
 9 
 
 X 
 
 1 
 
 
 Yonkers, N.Y. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 
 500 
 
 
 
 
 
 Norfolk, Va. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

 
 142 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 STATISTICS OF AMERICAN CITY COUNCILS (Continued) 
 
 
 SINGLE OR LARGER HOUSE 
 
 SMALLER HOUSE 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 (') 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 
 (') 
 
 1^0. OF 
 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 
 (0 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 (*) 
 
 Waterbury, Conn. 
 
 15 
 
 3X5 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Holyoke, Mass. 
 
 21 
 
 7 + 14 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fort Wayne, Ind. 
 
 20 
 
 2X10 
 
 2 
 
 $150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Youngstown, O. 
 
 10 
 
 7 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Houston, Tex. 
 
 12 
 
 A.L. 
 
 
 SO 
 
 
 
 
 
 Covington, Ky. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Akron, O. 
 
 10 
 
 7 + 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Dallas, Tex. 
 
 12 
 
 8 + 4 
 
 2 
 
 120 
 
 
 
 
 
 Saginaw, Mich. 
 
 20 
 
 1X20 
 
 2 
 
 2( 8 ) 
 
 
 
 
 
 Lancaster, Pa. 
 
 27 
 
 3X9 
 
 1 
 
 
 ? 
 
 
 
 
 Lincoln, Neb. 
 
 
 X7 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Brockton, Mass. 
 
 21 
 
 3X7 
 
 1 
 
 
 7 
 
 1X7 
 
 1 
 
 
 Binghamton, N.Y. 
 
 13 
 
 1X13 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Augusta, Ga. 
 
 15 
 
 3X5 
 
 3 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Pawtucket, R.I. 4 
 
 18 
 
 nx5 
 
 1 
 
 100 
 
 6 
 
 5 + 1 
 
 1 
 
 $150 
 
 Altoona, Pa. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Wheeling, W. Va. 
 
 28 
 
 nx8 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 4 
 
 none 
 
 Mobile, Ala. 
 
 8 
 
 1X8 
 
 3 
 
 none 
 
 7 
 
 A.L. 
 
 3 
 
 none 
 
 Birmingham, Ala. 
 
 18 
 
 2X9 
 
 4 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Little Rock, Ark. 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 2 
 
 120 
 
 
 
 
 
 Springfield, O. 
 
 9 
 
 6 + 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Galveston, Tex. 
 
 4 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 500 
 
 
 
 
 
 Tacoma, Wash. 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Haver hill, Mass. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 7 
 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 Spokane, Wash. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Terre Haute, Ind. 
 
 9 
 
 6 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Dubuque, la. 
 
 7 
 
 5 + 2 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Quincy, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 156 
 
 
 
 
 
 South Bend, Ind. 
 
 10 
 
 7 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 150 
 
 
 
 
 
 Salem, Mass. 
 
 24 
 
 4X6 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Johnstown, Pa. 
 
 21 
 
 1X21 
 
 2 
 
 
 21 
 
 1X21 
 
 4 
 
 
 Elmira, N.Y. 
 
 24 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 100 
 
 
 
 
 
 Allentown, Pa. 
 
 22 
 
 2X11 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Davenport, la. 
 
 8 
 
 6 + 2 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 McKeesport, Pa. 
 
 22 
 
 2X11 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 11 
 
 IX 11 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 Springfield, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 156 
 
 
 
 
 
 Chelsea, Mass. 
 
 15 
 
 5X10 
 
 1-2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Chester, Pa. 
 
 22 
 
 2X11 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 York, Pa. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Maiden, Mass. 
 
 21 
 
 3X7 
 
 1 
 
 
 7 
 
 1X7 
 
 1 
 
 
 Topeka, Kan. 
 
 
 X6 
 
 2 
 
 200 
 
 
 
 
 
 Newton, Mass. 
 
 21 
 
 14X7 
 
 1-2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Sioux City, la. 
 
 10 
 
 8X2 
 
 2 
 
 200 
 
 
 
 
 
 Bayonne, N.J. 
 
 11 
 
 10+1 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Knoxville, Tenn. 
 
 
 xii 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Chattanooga, Tenn. 
 
 12 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 100 
 
 8 
 
 1X8 
 
 2 
 
 75 
 
 Schenectady, N.Y. 
 
 22 
 
 
 2 
 
 75 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fitchburg, Mass. 
 
 18 
 
 3X6 
 
 1 
 
 
 6 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 Superior, Wis. 
 
 20 
 
 2X10 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 

 
 AMERICAN MUNICIPAL COUNCILS 
 
 143 
 
 STATISTICS OP AMERICAN CITY COUNCILS (Continued) 
 
 
 SINGLE OB LARGER HOUSE 
 
 SMALLER HOUSE 
 
 No. OF 
 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 
 (') 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 
 (') 
 
 No. OF 
 MEM- 
 BERS 
 
 How 
 
 CHOSEN 
 (') 
 
 TERM 
 
 SALARY 
 (0 
 
 Ilockford, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 $3(") 
 
 
 
 
 
 Taunton, Mass. 
 
 24 
 
 3X8 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 8 
 
 1X8 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 Canton, O. 
 
 9 
 
 6 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 ? 
 
 
 
 
 
 Butte, Mont. 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 2 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 
 
 Montgomery, Ala. 
 
 15 
 
 12 + 3 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Auburn, N.Y. 
 
 10 
 
 IX 10 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 East St. Louis, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 3() 
 
 
 
 
 
 Joliet, 111. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 3( 6 ) 
 
 
 
 
 
 Sacramento, Cal. 
 
 9 
 
 1X9 
 
 4 
 
 250 
 
 
 
 
 
 Racine, Wis. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 LaCrosse, Wis. 
 
 10 
 
 1X20 
 
 4 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Williamsport, Pa. 
 
 26 
 
 2X13 
 
 2 
 
 
 13 
 
 
 4 
 
 
 Jacksonville, Fla. 
 
 18 
 
 2X9 
 
 2 
 
 2( 6 ) 
 
 
 
 
 
 Newcastle, Pa. 
 
 14 
 
 2X7 
 
 
 
 7 
 
 
 
 
 Newport, Ky. 
 
 12 
 
 
 2 
 
 3() 
 
 5 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 $3(') 
 
 Oshkosh, Wis. 
 
 26 
 
 2X13 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 
 
 
 
 Woonsocket, R.I. 
 
 15 
 
 3X5 
 
 1 
 
 100 
 
 5 
 
 1x5 
 
 1 
 
 150 
 
 Pueblo, Colo. 
 
 8 
 
 1X8 
 
 2 
 
 390 
 
 
 
 
 
 Atlantic City, N.J. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Passaic, N.J. 
 
 13 
 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Bay City, Mich. 
 
 22 
 
 2X11 
 
 2 
 
 2() 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fort Worth, Tex. 
 
 9 
 
 1X9 
 
 2 
 
 96 
 
 
 
 
 
 Lexington, Ky. 
 
 12 
 
 
 2 
 
 3(") 
 
 8 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 3() 
 
 Gloucester, Mass. 
 
 24 
 
 3X8 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 8 
 
 1X8 
 
 1 
 
 none 
 
 South Omaha, Neb. 
 
 6 
 
 
 2 
 
 600 
 
 
 
 
 
 New Britain, Conn. 
 
 24 
 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 6 
 
 A.L. 
 
 2 
 
 none 
 
 Council Bluffs, la. 
 
 8 
 
 6+2 
 
 2 
 
 250 
 
 
 
 
 
 Cedar Rapids, la. 
 
 10 
 
 8 + 2 
 
 2 
 
 100 
 
 
 
 
 
 Easton, Pa. 
 
 24 
 
 2X12 
 
 2 
 
 
 12 
 
 1X12 
 
 4 
 
 
 Jackson, Mich. 
 
 16 
 
 2X8 
 
 2 
 
 75 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 The multiplication sign ( x ) indicates election by wards or districts, 
 the first figure showing the number of members from each district (n 
 indicating a variable number), and the second figure showing the num- 
 ber of districts. 
 
 The plus sign (+) indicates election partly by districts and partly 
 at large. The figure given first shows the number of members elected 
 by wards; the second figure shows the number elected at large. 
 
 A. L. indicates election at large, on a general ticket for the whole 
 city without ward or district members. 
 
 2 Annual salary is given except where otherwise noted. 
 
 3 No city council. 
 
 4 A small property qualification is required of electors for the city 
 council. 
 
 5 Members of two administrative boards act jointly as the city council. 
 8 Per meeting.
 
 VIII 
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 
 IN THE UNITED STATES 1 
 
 DURING the past few years there has been much agitation 
 in the United States in favor of the extension of municipal 
 functions. This has had particular reference to undertak- 
 ings which have hitherto been operated by private corpora- 
 tions acting under special franchises for the use of the public 
 streets. There has been a corresponding amount of dis- 
 cussion in opposition to such proposals, which has been 
 strengthened by the criticism in Great Britain of what in 
 that country has been called municipal trading. It is not the 
 purpose of this article to consider the arguments on either 
 side of this prolonged debate; but it is intended simply to 
 present a brief record of recent legislation, showing the de- 
 velopment of municipal activities in our own country. 
 
 It is no easy matter to bring together even the most im- 
 portant facts for such an account. The legislation on the 
 subject is not only voluminous, but most of it applies to 
 particular cities, and much of it deals with petty details, 2 
 which make it difficult to realize the general tendencies. 
 
 Within the period to be covered, however, there have been 
 a few municipal laws of a general nature, which stand out in 
 
 1 Rewritten from articles in the Annals of the American Academy 
 of Social and Political Science, March, 1905, and the New York State 
 Library Reviews of State Legislation. 
 
 2 Thus in 1904 there were 66 special city laws for particular cities in 
 New York State, 43 in Massachusetts, 40 in Louisiana, 25 in Maryland, 
 and even 10 in Virginia where a comprehensive general law had been 
 enacted the previous year. Of the New York laws no less than 21 applied 
 to New York City, including acts for such trivial matters as a change 
 in the salaries of chaplains in the fire department, and creating the office 
 of chief lineman for the police telegraph service. 
 
 L 145
 
 146 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 marked contrast to the prevailing system of special legisla- 
 tion. ,The most important of these is the municipal code of 
 Ohio, enacted in 1902, to correct a situation brought about 
 by decisions of the Supreme Court of that state. These 
 decisions had declared unconstitutional a great mass of 
 legislation passed during the preceding fifty years, to cir- 
 cumvent the constitutional requirement of general uniform 
 legislation. This new code gives to every municipality in 
 the state the same authority, and thus has extended to all 
 every power previously exercised by any one. In 1903 the 
 Virginia assembly passed a law reenacting and amending 
 the statutes in reference to cities and towns, to meet the 
 conditions of the new state constitution; and in the same 
 year a New Jersey act was passed for the government of all 
 cities which adopt it. In 1905 a new municipal code was 
 enacted in Indiana. 
 
 The general tendency of these and other measures is in 
 the direction of increasing the functions of municipalities in 
 the United States, but at the same time to do so by continu- 
 ing the policy of specific enumerated grants of power and 
 minute legislative control over the cities. There is no evi- 
 dence of any change to the policy of the countries of con- 
 tinental Europe, where cities have general authority to 
 undertake any functions affecting the interests of the city, 
 subject only to the specific restrictions and regulations im- 
 posed by the central administration. Along with this increase 
 in the active operations of cities may be noted a tendency 
 to restrict the discretion of city councils in granting franchises 
 conferring special privileges in the public streets. 
 
 PUBLIC SAFETY 
 
 Turning to an examination of more specific functions, we 
 may note first the situation in the field of public safety, or 
 the measures for protecting life, liberty, and property. Here 
 the most striking changes have been, not in the direction of 
 extending municipal activities, but in the assumption by the
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 147 
 
 states of functions formerly left to local communities. This 
 has been done in two ways: by the establishment of small 
 bodies of state police, for service throughout the state ; and 
 by giving the management of municipal police to state-ap- 
 pointed boards. 
 
 Apparently the first action in reference to a distinctively 
 state police was taken by Massachusetts in 1865, when a 
 small force of state constables was established mainly for 
 the enforcement of the law prohibiting the liquor traffic. 
 On the repeal of the prohibition law in 1875 the state police 
 was continued as a detective force to aid in the suppression 
 of disorder and the enforcement of criminal laws, and its 
 functions have since been extended to include the inspection 
 of factories. More recently the office of fire marshal, for the 
 investigation of fires, has been incorporated with the state 
 police. 1 Rhode Island in 1886 established a chief of state 
 police with powers of direction over the sheriffs and local po- 
 lice, in connection with the enforcement of the prohibition 
 law then reenacted in that state. 2 But this office lasted 
 only a few years. Another brief experiment with state police 
 was made by New Jersey from 1891 to 1894. 
 
 Soon after the establishment of the system of state liquor 
 dispensaries, South Carolina (in 1896) established a force of 
 state constables to aid in the enforcement of liquor laws. 3 
 A statute of 1903 further regulates the organization of this 
 force. The governor appoints the chief state constable, who 
 receives a salary of $1500 a year, and this officer appoints 
 seven assistant chief constables and other state constables to 
 assist him in his work. Connecticut has also organized a body 
 of state police (in 1903) similar to that in Massachusetts, 
 specially for the enforcement of the laws relating to intoxi- 
 
 1 R. H. Whitten, Public Administration in Massachusetts, ch. 6. 
 (Columbia University Studies, Vol. VIII.) 
 
 2 C. M. L. Sites, Centralized Administration of Liquor Laws, p. 72. 
 (Columbia University Studies, Vol. X.) 
 
 3 Ibid., pp. 73, 118.
 
 148 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 eating liquors and gaming, and taking over the functions of 
 the state fire marshal. There is provided a superintendent 
 of police at $3000 a year, an assistant superintendent, and 
 from five to ten police officers, all selected by a board of five 
 unpaid commissioners, who in turn are to be chosen biennially 
 by the judges of the Superior Court. 
 
 In 1905 a similar force of state police was organized in 
 Pennsylvania, for use primarily in the mining regions. It 
 to some extent takes the place of the coal and iron police 
 formerly employed by the mining corporations, but also 
 serves to save the state the frequent use of the state militia 
 to suppress disorders in time of extensive strikes. It consists 
 of a superintendent and four companies aggregating 230 
 men, appointed after a physical and mental examination. 
 
 Of a somewhat different nature are the bodies of mounted 
 rangers established in less settled regions for the suppression 
 of violent disorder and the protection of the Mexican frontier. 
 The Texas rangers, organized in 1901, may consist of four 
 companies, each composed of twenty-two men, the captains 
 and the quartermaster in command of the whole force being 
 appointed by the governor of the state. In Arizona the 
 rangers as reorganized in 1903 consist of twenty-six men 
 mustered into service by the governor of the territory. Both 
 in Texas and Arizona the governors strongly commend the 
 work of these rangers; and in 1905 a company of mounted 
 police was established for similar purposes in the territory of 
 New Mexico. 
 
 State-appointed police boards for particular cities have 
 been established for some time in a considerable number of 
 cities. New York had such a board from 1857 to 1870; 
 and during that period similar boards were established for 
 large cities in other states. Then came a period when most 
 of the state boards were abolished. But since 1885 there 
 has been a revival of this system; and it is in existence in 
 St. Louis, Boston, Baltimore, San Francisco, Kansas City, 
 Mo., Fall River, St. Joseph, Birmingham, Manchester, N.H.,
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 149 
 
 and eleven Indiana cities. 1 Still more recently state police 
 boards were provided for Newport and Providence, R.I., 
 but these have since been put in process of extinction. The 
 new Ohio code contains a provision under which boards of 
 public safety are appointed by the governor of the state 
 when the mayor's nominations are not confirmed by two- 
 thirds of the council; and in a number of cities the governor 
 has been called on to act under this provision. In 1905 
 state police boards were provided for the New Hampshire 
 cities of Keene and Berlin. In Indiana, however, a statute 
 of 1901 to place the police and fire departments of Fort 
 Wayne, Terre Haute, and South Bend under state boards 
 of public safety has been declared unconstitutional. The 
 police of Cincinnati and Denver have within the past few 
 years been transferred from the control of state boards to 
 locally appointed authorities. 
 
 In 1906 the state police board for Boston was replaced by 
 a single commissioner and an excise board; but both of 
 these authorities are appointed by the governor and council. 
 
 A good deal of legislation has also been enacted in regard 
 to local boards of police and fire commissioners. Special 
 mention may be made of a Louisiana Act of 1904 reorganiz- 
 ing the police administration of New Orleans. And in 1907, 
 a special act has greatly increased the authority of the police 
 commissioner of New York City over the subordinate police 
 officers in that city. 
 
 One of the most important developments of municipal 
 activity in the field of public safety has been the work of the 
 new tenement house department in the city of New York 
 established in 1902. This department took over the powers 
 over tenement houses formerly exercised by the departments 
 of health, fire, and police, and has important additional 
 powers under the statutes providing for the new department. 
 It conducts an elaborate system of inspections of old buildings, 
 
 1 Terre Haute, South Bend, Anderson, Elkhart, Richmond, Hunt- 
 ington, Jeffersonville, La Fayette, Logansport, Muncie, and New Albany.
 
 150 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and requires repairs and improvements so as to render them 
 sanitary, safe, and habitable. It also supervises the con- 
 struction of new buildings, and makes systematic inspections 
 to see that there are no violations of the provisions of the 
 law to secure stability of structure, protection from fire, and 
 adequate sanitary conditions. But the requirements of the 
 law still permit a much greater degree of compact building 
 in New York than in the largest cities of Europe. In Germany, 
 dwelling houses even in the business sections must have at 
 least one-third of the area of building lots left as courtyards, 
 and in residence sections at least a half. 1 In New York only 
 one-fourth of the lot area must be left unbuilt. 
 
 PUBLIC WORKS 
 
 Steady advance is being made by American cities in pro- 
 viding street paving, street cleaning, garbage disposal, sewer 
 systems, parks, and similar public improvements. This 
 development, however, is rather the extension of established 
 fields of municipal action than the inauguration of a new 
 policy. But it is significant of the niggardly methods in 
 legislative grants of municipal powers that even for these 
 functions, clearly accepted as within the proper scope of 
 municipal work, a great deal of additional legislation must 
 be passed every year authorizing the necessary undertakings 
 and modifying the methods of procedure and assessment. 
 In regard to street paving, a novel feature has been the 
 establishment of municipal asphalt plants in Detroit and some 
 other cities, to repair and resurface asphalt pavements by 
 direct labor instead of making contracts for this class of 
 work. In a number of cities direct municipal labor may now 
 be employed in place of contracts for a large variety of public 
 improvements. Some street cleaning is now done in most 
 American cities; and with comparatively few exceptions by 
 a force of municipal employees. The latest returns on this 
 subject are shown in the following table: 2 
 
 1 C. Hugo, Deutsche Stadtverwaltung, pp. 429, 430. 
 > Engineering News, XLVIII, 422.
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 151 
 
 GROUPS OF CITIES 
 
 NUMBER OP 
 PLACES 
 
 NUMBER 
 REPORTING 
 STREET 
 CLEANING 
 
 MUNICI- 
 PAL EM- 
 PLOYEES 
 
 CONTRACT 
 
 BOTH 
 
 Over 30,000 pop'n . . 
 
 135 
 
 132 
 
 115 
 
 9 
 
 7 
 
 10,000-30,000 . . . 
 
 304 
 
 291 
 
 272 
 
 13 
 
 4 
 
 5,000-10,000 . . . 
 
 465 
 
 435 
 
 386 
 
 30 
 
 9 
 
 3,000- 5,000 . . . 
 
 620 
 
 16 
 
 466 
 
 31 
 
 5 
 
 
 1524 
 
 874 
 
 1239 
 
 83 
 
 25 
 
 Probably the most extensive scheme of municipal engineer- 
 ing works in recent years have been those connected with 
 the reconstruction of Baltimore after the disastrous fire of 
 February, 1904. A series of special acts in 1904 established 
 a special commission to prepare and execute plans for street 
 improvements, public squares, and market-places, the en- 
 largement of the harbors and wharves ; and authorized loans 
 aggregating $19,000,000 for street improvements, sewerage, 
 and parks. In 1906 an additional loan of $5,000,000 for 
 street improvements was authorized. In NBW Orleans, also, 
 an extensive system of underground sewers has at last 
 been constructed, and important additions to the public 
 wharves and warehouses have been undertaken. 
 
 Many smaller cities are introducing public sewers ; and the 
 general situation in regard to sewerage systems is indicated 
 in the following table : 1 
 
 GROUPS OF CITIES 
 
 NUMBER 
 OF PLACES 
 
 NUMBER 
 
 WITH 
 
 SEWERS 
 
 PUBLIC 
 WORKS 
 
 PRIVATE 
 COM- 
 PANIES 
 
 Over 30,000 
 
 135 
 
 131 
 
 131 
 
 
 10,000-30,000 
 
 303 
 
 277 
 
 269 
 
 8 
 
 5,000-10,000 
 
 463 
 
 364 
 
 346 
 
 15 
 
 3,000- 5,000 
 
 623 
 
 324 
 
 299 
 
 19 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1524 
 
 1096 
 
 1045 
 
 42 
 
 Municipal Year Book, 1902.
 
 152 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Two undertakings of special importance for the final dis- 
 posal of sewage should also be noted. In 1900 the Chicago 
 drainage canal was opened, much to the improvement of the 
 Chicago River ; and since then there has been a steady prog- 
 ress in the work of connecting other parts of the sewer net- 
 work in the drainage district with the canal. In 1902 a state 
 commission was established in New Jersey to construct trunk 
 outfall sewers to carry the drainage from the cities of the 
 densely populated Passaic Valley, and a year later the issue 
 of $9,000,000 in fifty-year bonds was authorized for this work. 
 
 Other works for the improvement of sanitary conditions 
 are water purification plants. The most important new 
 works of this kind are those under way in Philadelphia and 
 Pittsburg. 
 
 Any important addition to the park systems of American 
 cities seems to require additional legislation, and numerous 
 acts in regard to parks are passed every year. Among the 
 more important may be noted a series of Illinois acts, in 1905, 
 intended for the city of Chicago, which granted additional 
 bonding and taxing power for park purposes, in order to 
 provide new small parks and an outer belt of parks. An act 
 of 1900 authorized the city of New York to establish a sea- 
 side park in or near the city, where municipal hospitals may 
 be erected. The Rhode Island legislature has established 
 a metropolitan park commission for Providence and the 
 surrounding cities and towns. 
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP 
 
 Attempts to extend municipal activity into the disputed 
 field of " public utilities " meet with varying degrees of suc- 
 cess with respect to different classes of undertakings. New 
 municipal waterworks are frequently authorized and estab- 
 lished. In 1904 no less than thirty acts were passed for 
 the construction or extension of such works in particular 
 cities. Memphis is the most important city to change recently 
 from a private to a municipal plant. Extensive new water-
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 153 
 
 supply systems have been authorized for New York City and 
 Cincinnati. Municipal electric lighting plants have also 
 been increasing in number and importance. Municipal 
 street railways are still only in the stage of discussion and 
 agitation. 
 
 Recent investigations make possible a definite record of 
 the status of municipal undertakings of these kinds. In 
 reference to waterworks, the following table shows the 
 situation in 1902 1 1 
 
 GROUPS OF CITIES 
 
 TOTAL 
 NUMBER OF 
 WATER- 
 WORKS 
 
 NUMBER OF 
 MUNICIPAL, 
 WORKS 
 
 PER CENT 
 
 MUNICIPAL 
 
 Over 30,000 population .... 
 10,000-30,000 population . . . 
 5,000-10,000 population . . . 
 3,000-5,000 population . . . 
 
 135 
 
 302 
 
 458 
 580 
 
 95 
 
 152 
 234 
 318 
 
 70.4 
 50 
 50.1 
 50.5 
 
 New England States 
 
 226 
 
 143 
 
 63.2 
 
 Middle States 
 
 335 
 
 140 
 
 41.7 
 
 North Central States 
 
 372 
 
 243 
 
 65.3 
 
 Northwestern States 
 
 150 
 
 86 
 
 57.3 
 
 South Atlantic States 
 
 107 
 
 64 
 
 59.8 
 
 South Central States 
 
 91 
 
 36 
 
 39.5 
 
 Southwestern States .... 
 
 124 
 
 55 
 
 43 5 
 
 Pacific States 
 
 70 
 
 32 
 
 45 7 
 
 
 
 
 
 United States 
 
 1475 
 
 799 
 
 542 
 
 
 
 
 
 A more exhaustive investigation, including the smaller 
 towns, made in 1898 by the United States Department of 
 Labor, showed a total of 1787 municipal waterworks, and 
 1539 under private control. It should be noted, however, 
 that the higher proportion of municipal works among the 
 large cities increases the significance of municipal works as 
 a whole. In 1898 the total investment in municipal plants 
 was nearly double that in private works. 2 
 
 From the census report on central electric light and power 
 
 1 Municipal Year Book, 1902, pp. xxix, xxxi. 
 
 2 Report of the Commissioner of Labor, 1899, p. 12.
 
 154 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 stations, the following data have been compiled showing the 
 number and distribution of municipal plants in 1902 : * 
 
 GBOUPS OF CITIES 
 
 TOTAL NUMBER 
 ELECTRIC 
 STATIONS 
 
 NUMBER 
 MUNICIPAL 
 
 PER CENT 
 MUNICIPAL. 
 
 New England States 
 
 314 
 
 35 
 
 11.1 
 
 Middle States 
 
 641 
 
 79 
 
 12.3 
 
 North Central States 
 
 1112 
 
 341 
 
 30.7 
 
 Northwestern Spates 
 
 511 
 
 145 
 
 28.4 
 
 South Atlantic States .... 
 
 209 
 
 64 
 
 30.6 
 
 South Central States 
 
 205 
 
 64 
 
 31.2 
 
 Southwestern States 
 
 381 
 
 62 
 
 16.3 
 
 Pacific States 
 
 251 
 
 25 
 
 10 
 
 
 
 
 
 United States 
 
 3624 
 
 815 
 
 22.5 
 
 
 
 
 
 As municipal electric light works are found mostly in small 
 cities, these figures exaggerate the importance of municipal 
 lighting. Measured by horse power and output in kilowatts, 
 the municipal plants furnish about 8 per cent or 9 per cent 
 of the electric lighting and about 20 per cent of the public 
 street lighting. In the states where municipal plants are 
 most frequent the proportion is naturally much higher, the 
 maximum for any state being found in Michigan, where 
 municipal plants furnish about 30 per cent of the total electric 
 lighting and nearly two-thirds of the public street lighting. 
 
 Municipal gas-works are still very infrequent in the United 
 States. In 1902 there were only twenty, as compared with 
 961 cities with private gas-works ; while the municipal works 
 are in small cities, and their total output is less than one 
 per cent of the illuminating gas produced. 2 
 
 While there is now no street railway operated by a munici- 
 pal government in this country, Boston and New York have 
 extensive municipal underground roads, which are leased 
 for a term of years to operating companies. To the original 
 Boston subway, completed some years ago, there has been 
 added a tunnel under the harbor to East Boston, and a new 
 
 1 Census Bulletin, Nov. 5, 1903. 
 
 2 Census Bulletin, No. 123.
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 155 
 
 subway under Washington Street; while additional lines 
 are to be built to Cambridge and other places in the metro- 
 politan district. A much larger undertaking has been the 
 New York subway. The first lines contracted for, sixteen 
 miles in length and costing $35,000,000, were opened to service 
 in October, 1904; a second line under the East River to 
 Brooklyn is practically completed; and many additional 
 lines have been planned. 
 
 In addition to the special legislation authorizing particular 
 municipal undertakings of this kind for individual cities, 
 there has been enacted within the past few years a number 
 of statutes conferring broader and more general authority 
 on cities. The new Ohio municipal code authorizes munici- 
 pal waterworks and electric lighting plants in every city 
 in that state; and the law governing bond issues confers 
 financial powers sufficient to make the grant effective. A 
 Missouri act of 1903, applying to cities of less than 30,000 
 population, is the broadest in the scope of powers conferred. 
 This authorizes such municipalities to undertake any public 
 utility, and specifies not only waterworks and light, heat, 
 and power plants, but also telephones and street railways. 
 Such undertakings will be under the control of a board of 
 public works consisting of four members appointed by the 
 mayor and council, not more than two of the same political 
 party. This act is, however, not likely to extend very largely 
 the scope of municipal action, as there is no provision for 
 financing these undertakings either by the issue of bonds or 
 in any other way. A Kansas act of the same year authorizes, 
 in cities under 15,000 population, municipal waterworks, 
 and gas, oil, and electric plants, to secure which bonds may be 
 issued on a vote of the electors, up to the general debt limit 
 of 15 per cent of the assessed value of the property. The 
 general municipal act for larger Kansas cities only provides 
 for municipal water and lighting plants at some time in the 
 future, but Atchison and Leavenworth have received special 
 authority to establish municipal waterworks.
 
 156 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 A California act of 1903, amending the powers of cities 
 under 3000 population, adds authority to establish and 
 manage waterworks, wharves, street railways, telephone 
 and telegraph lines, and lighting and heating plants; but 
 like the Missouri act, this fails to give adequate financial 
 powers. Under the new general municipal law in Virginia, 
 cities are authorized to provide waterworks; and bonds 
 issued with the approval of the voters for this or other rev- 
 enue-producing undertakings are not included within the 
 debt limit so long as the revenue is sufficient to pay the cost 
 of maintenance, interest on bonds and insurance, and to 
 provide a sinking-fund. 
 
 Perhaps the most significant statute of recent years pro- 
 viding for an extension of municipal administration in this 
 direction is an Illinois act of 1903, authorizing the cities in 
 that state to own and operate street railways. This act is 
 of special importance because, in addition to the formal 
 grant of authority, there is a careful attempt to provide 
 a satisfactory method of meeting the serious financial diffi- 
 culties involved in this new departure, so that the grant of 
 power might be effective and adequate whenever it is con- 
 sidered advisable to make use of the authority. 
 
 This act applies to all cities in the state of Illinois, but 
 before any of the powers conferred can be exercised, the act 
 must first be adopted as a whole by popular referendum in 
 the city concerned, while additional referendum votes must 
 be taken in reference to various special features of the law. 
 The authority given is "to construct, acquire, purchase, 
 maintain, and operate street railways within the corporate 
 limits," and franchises granted before this power is acted on 
 may contain a reservation of the right on the part of the city 
 to take over the plant at some future time. Two methods 
 are provided for securing funds for purchasing or construct- 
 ing municipal railways. .General city bonds may be issued, 
 provided the proposition is submitted to popular vote and 
 approved by two-thirds of those voting, but the debt limit
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 157 
 
 is almost certain to prevent this method from being adopted. 
 The other alternative and this is the most striking feature 
 of the act is to issue street railway certificates, secured 
 by a mortgage on the railway, giving the mortgagee in case 
 of foreclosure the right to maintain and operate the road 
 for a period of not over twenty years. An ordinance provid- 
 ing for such certificates must, however, be submitted to 
 popular vote and be approved by a majority of those voting 
 on the question. It was expected that such certificates would 
 not be considered by the courts as part of the city debt 
 limited by the state constitution. When a city has secured 
 a street railway, it may operate it under direct municipal 
 management only if that policy is approved at a popular 
 referendum by three-fifths of those voting. Or the city 
 may lease the road for a period of not over twenty years, but 
 any ordinance authorizing a lease for more than five years 
 must be submitted to a referendum vote on the petition of 
 10 per cent of the voters. 
 
 Under this law the city of Chicago in 1906 voted for a 
 municipal street railway system; but the proposition for 
 municipal operation failed to receive the necessary three- 
 fifths vote. A year later a new agreement with the railway 
 companies was approved by popular vote; and soon after- 
 wards the Supreme Court of Illinois held that money borrowed 
 on the proposed street railway certificates must be considered 
 part of the city debt, the total of which is closely limited 
 by the state constitution. Under these conditions municipal 
 street railways are not likely to be established under this 
 act. 1 
 
 Under the new Indiana municipal code of 1905 municipal 
 waterworks, gas-works and electric light, heat and power 
 plants may be established, after a referendum vote in each 
 case. But the low debt limit of two per cent of the assessed 
 valuation will prevent any extensive exercise of such powers. 
 In 1906 several acts were passed by the New Jersey legisla- 
 
 1 Cf. Essay XII.
 
 158 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ture authorizing, in general terms, municipal water, Iight 7 
 heat, and power plants. The borrowing power for light, heat, 
 and power plants is closely limited, but greater freedom is 
 granted with reference to waterworks. 
 
 The financial provisions of the Illinois street railway law 
 of 1903 are being copied to some extent in other states. A 
 Missouri law of 1905, authorizing municipal waterworks in 
 cities with a population of 3000 to 30,000, provided that the 
 funds should be raised by mortgage certificates on the plant. 
 And an Iowa act of 1906 authorizes mortgage bonds on 
 municipal water plants. This method of financing munici- 
 pal enterprises seems to offer a safe means for making ex- 
 periments in new fields, without removing the limitations 
 on the general municipal debt. But in view of the recent 
 decision of the Illinois Supreme Court, it is rather doubtful 
 whether it can be generally employed without amending the 
 state constitutions. 
 
 In the new Oklahoma constitution it is provided that 
 11 every municipal corporation . . . shall have the right to 
 engage in any business or enterprise which may be engaged 
 in by a person, firm or corporation by virtue of a franchise 
 from said corporation." But this sweeping grant will need 
 to be supplemented by adequate financial power to become 
 effective. 
 
 FRANCHISES AND PUBLIC CONTROL 
 
 Since 1900 a number of states have established general 
 conditions for franchises dealing with municipal services, 
 and authorized municipal regulation of private companies 
 operating such services. A California law of 1901 provides 
 that sales of franchises must be advertised, and that the 
 city must receive at least two per cent of the gross receipts 
 after five years. A South Carolina statute of 1902 authorizes 
 the grant of franchises for light and water-supply, for a term 
 of not over thirty years, on a two-thirds vote of the city 
 council, confirmed by a majority vote of the electors. The 
 new Ohio code provides that street railroad franchises may
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 159 
 
 be granted, for not more than twenty-five years, only after 
 three weeks' notice, to those who offer the lowest rates of 
 fare and have secured the consent of property owners repre- 
 senting the greater part of the route. 
 
 In the new Virginia constitution it is provided that fran- 
 chises for the use of the public streets shall not be granted 
 without the consent of the municipal authorities, nor for a 
 term of more than thirty years; and that they may contain 
 provisions for public purchase at the expiration of the term. 
 These constitutional requirements have been supplemented 
 by an act of 1903 regulating the granting of franchises, which 
 was afterward incorporated with some additions in the new 
 general municipal act. It is now provided that the streets 
 and public property of cities and towns shall not be alienated 
 except by a vote of three-fourths of the council, and streets 
 may not be used for street railways, water systems, gas-pipes, 
 telephones, and similar purposes, except with the consent of 
 the municipal authorities. Franchises must be limited to 
 not more than thirty years; and elaborate provisions are 
 established to insure publicity and competitive bidding. 
 Advertisements inviting bids must be published for four 
 weeks ; bids must be opened and read in public session of the 
 council ; if the highest bid is not accepted, the franchise ordi- 
 nance must state the reasons for preferring a lower bid, and 
 no amendments may be made in the terms of the grant with- 
 out public advertisement for ten days. The courts are given 
 authority to enforce by mandamus the terms of the grant. 
 Such a franchise grant may provide that at its expiration the 
 plant as well as the property in the streets may revert to 
 the city either without compensation or on a fair valuation 
 of the property, but without including any value for the fran- 
 chise. The city may then sell or lease the property, or, if 
 authorized by law, may maintain and operate it. 1 
 
 *The special franchise law of 1903 was repealed in 1904; but this 
 probably does not affect the practically identical provisions in the gen- 
 eral municipal corporations act, which was passed after the franchise 
 law.
 
 160 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The Kansas act of 1903 for cities over 15,000 population 
 limits the term of franchises to not more than thirty years, 
 but contains none of the provisions for publicity such as are 
 contained in the Virginia act. It does, however, authorize 
 the councils of such cities to prescribe reasonable rates for 
 water, electricity, gas, telephones, or other commodity fur- 
 nished by virtue of a franchise, the question of the reasonable- 
 ness of the rate fixed being subject to review by the district 
 judges. Waterworks may be purchased by a city ten years 
 after a grant has been made, but in the case of gas or electric 
 works or street railways the city may acquire only on the 
 termination of a future grant, and when it secures possession 
 can only lease the plant or make a contract for operation. 
 Provisions are made for appraising the value of the plant 
 in case of purchase. By another act cities of less than 15,000 
 population may grant franchises for only twenty years, and 
 the mayor and council may make contracts and fix rates to 
 private consumers. 
 
 Some other acts may also be briefly noted. A Minnesota 
 act of 1903 authorizes city councils to contract for water- 
 supply for a term not over thirty years, and for lighting for 
 a term not over fifteen years, if there is no municipal plant. 
 No further conditions are imposed. Wisconsin and Montana 
 provided in the same year for a referendum on franchises: 
 in the first-named state on the petition of twenty per cent 
 of the voters ; in the second-named, the approval of the resi- 
 dent freeholders is an essential requirement. In New York 
 City the power of granting franchises was transferred, in 
 1905, from the council to the board of estimate and appor- 
 tionment. A new charter to the city of Grand Rapids, Mich., 
 in 1905, contains elaborate regulations in regard to the grant 
 of franchises. A New Jersey law of 1906 provides that fran- 
 chises in the streets and public places must require a peti- 
 tion and public notice; and grants by councils are limited 
 to twenty years, but on a referendum, franchises for forty 
 years may be granted.
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 161 
 
 On the other hand, in the new Indiana municipal code, 
 restrictions in the granting of franchises are much relaxed. 
 Formerly franchises were limited to 10 and 34 years accord- 
 ing to the purpose, and contracts for street lighting were 
 limited to 10 years. By the new code, not only are all fran- 
 chises previously granted made legal, but new franchises 
 may be granted with no limit as to the term or other con- 
 ditions ; while contracts for a supply of light, water, or heat 
 for city purposes may be made for as long a period as 25 years. 
 Kansas and Colorado acts of the same year (1905) regulating 
 the granting of franchises in these states also provide very 
 inadequate protection to the public interests. 
 
 Measures providing a more continuous system of public 
 control over private franchise corporations have been enacted 
 in several states. A New York act of 1905 established 
 a state gas and electricity commission, similar to that pre- 
 viously existing in Massachusetts, with large powers over 
 both public and private plants, including supervision of 
 accounts, control of capitalization, and regulation of rates. 
 In 1907 this commission and the state railroad commission 
 were abolished; and two new commissions were established, 
 one for the metropolitan district and one for the remainder 
 of the state, each exercising control over all public utility 
 corporations. Both commissions are appointed by the gov- 
 ernor, but the expenses of the board for the metropolitan 
 district are to be met by the local authorities. In Wisconsin, 
 by statute of 1907, the railroad commission has been given 
 full powers of supervision and control over all public utilities. 
 
 In New York and Massachusetts the state legislatures 
 have in 1906 directly regulated the price of gas in the largest 
 cities. For the two principal boroughs of New York City 
 the price of gas was fixed at 80 cents per thousand feet ; but 
 the application of this rate has been restrained, pending pro- 
 ceedings in the courts. In Boston and surrounding cities 
 and towns a sliding scale has been established, similar to 
 that in force in London for many years. At the standard
 
 162 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 price of 90 cents per thousand feet, dividends are limited to 
 7 per cent on the capital stock, the amount of which has 
 also been controlled by previous legislation. For each one 
 cent reduction in the price of gas, dividends may be increased 
 one fifth of one per cent. If the price is maintained so high 
 that large profits accumulate, these are to be distributed to 
 the local treasuries. After ten years the standard price may 
 be altered by the state gas and electric commission. 
 
 Local authorities have also been given larger powers of 
 control, especially in some of the southwestern states. Thus 
 in Arkansas, by act of 1903, city councils have been given 
 power to fix reasonable rates for water, gas, and electricity, 
 on complaint and after examination. A Missouri act of the 
 same year gave to cities under 30,000 population the same 
 authority, with the addition of telephones. A Mississippi act 
 of 1904 authorized municipal control of water and lighting 
 rates. And two Texas acts of 1905 require all street railway, 
 lighting, water, and sewer companies to make annual reports 
 to the Secretary of State, and provide for the regulation of 
 rates charged by such public utility corporations on com- 
 plaint of city councils before the district courts. 
 
 In the agreement concluded lately between the city of 
 Chicago and the street railway companies there are unusual 
 powers of control reserved by the municipal authorities, 
 so that the agreement may be said to establish a joint part- 
 nership between the city and the companies. Definite 
 arrangements are made for the purchase of the plant by the 
 city, or its transfer to other companies at a fixed price for 
 the existing property and the actual cost of improvements. 
 New construction is to be performed under the direct super- 
 vision of a board of engineers representing both the city and 
 the companies. Elaborate provisions are made in regard 
 to the service, providing for new routes, transfers, and exten- 
 sions. And the profits, after paying five per cent on the 
 value of the property, are to be divided between the city and 
 the companies in the ratio of 55 to 45. Under the new
 
 RECENT LEGISLATION ON MUNICIPAL FUNCTIONS 163 
 
 Oklahoma constitution, no exclusive franchises are allowed; 
 and all franchises must be limited to twenty-five years, must 
 be approved by popular vote, and are subject to the control 
 and regulation of the state and its subordinate subdivisions. 
 
 With such restrictions in franchises and public regulation, 
 it is clear that, even if municipal operation of such services 
 does not become common, a larger degree of public control 
 over the private companies is at least being established. 
 There is perhaps some need for distinguishing between the 
 relative importance of different conditions. Those requiring 
 previous public notice and local consent are clearly to be 
 commended at all times. The limitation of franchise terms 
 to between twenty or thirty years is an essential condition 
 if other means of control are lacking. But if a city reserves 
 the right to revise the payments to the city at short intervals, 
 to regulate rates and conditions of service, and to purchase 
 the plant for the value of the tangible property, there is less 
 need for limiting closely the duration of the franchise; and 
 for certain works involving vast amounts of fixed capital a 
 longer period than thirty years may be necessary.
 
 IX 
 
 PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION IN AMERICAN 
 
 CITIES ' 
 
 PUBLIC works administration in the cities of the United 
 States presents the most confusing variety of methods. For 
 particular branches of work there are boards and single com- 
 missioners, often both systems existing in the same city. 
 These officers are most frequently appointed by the mayor 
 with the consent of the city council; but there are many 
 exceptional cases where appointments are made sometimes 
 by the mayor alone, sometimes by the governor of the state, 
 occasionally by judges, and in some cities some officials are 
 chosen directly by popular vote. In many cities there is 
 some attempt made to coordinate and organize the work of 
 several of the most closely related branches of public improve- 
 ments, but it is seldom that this organization is complete, 
 and in many cases each branch of work is conducted indepen- 
 dently of all the others. 
 
 It may be of service to note the leading features of public 
 works administration in some of the leading cities. This 
 showing will at least emphasize the existing confusion. It 
 should demonstrate the need for a more systematic manage- 
 ment. And it may suggest some definite scheme of organi- 
 zation. 
 
 Under the New York charter of 1897 there was provided 
 a board of public improvements consisting of a president, 
 six commissioners for various public works' departments, 
 and, as ex officio members, the mayor, corporation counsel, 
 the comptroller, and the presidents of the five boroughs. 
 The president of the board and the six department commis- 
 
 1 Revised from Municipal Engineering, XXII, 212 (April, 1902). 
 
 164
 
 PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION 165 
 
 sioners were each appointed by the mayor, as was also the 
 corporation counsel; while the mayor, comptroller, and 
 borough presidents were chosen by popular vote. The board 
 controlled the general plan for public works, while the execu- 
 tion of these plans and the maintenance of existing work 
 was under the management of the different commissioners 
 for water supply, for highways, for street cleaning, for sewers, 
 for bridges, and for public buildings, lighting, and supplies. 
 Entirely independent of these departments and the board 
 of public improvements were a number of other departments 
 engaged in municipal works. The parks were placed under 
 the control of three commissioners, each having jurisdiction 
 of the parks in one section of the city ; the docks and ferries 
 were placed under a board of three members ; and the con- 
 struction of the new East River bridge was placed in charge 
 of a special board all of these officials being appointed by 
 the mayor. In addition, the construction of new water- 
 supply works and the rapid transit subway were under per- 
 manent boards appointed by state authority. 
 
 The amended charter which went into effect in 1902 made 
 some important changes in this system. The board of public 
 improvements has been abolished, and its powers assigned 
 partly to the board of estimate and apportionment, partly 
 to the various officers charged with special departments. The 
 five elected borough presidents are given control over the 
 highways, sewers, and public buildings in their respective 
 boroughs, and they have established and appointed in each 
 borough a commissioner of public works, subordinate to 
 whom are a superintendent of highways, a superintendent 
 of sewers, a superintendent of public buildings, and a super- 
 intendent of incumbrances, while in the borough of Man- 
 hattan there will also be a superintendent of baths. The 
 commissioners of street cleaning and bridges remain as before, 
 with jurisdiction over the entire city, the latter absorbing 
 the powers of the new East River bridge commission; and 
 the commissioner of water-supply has added to his depart-
 
 166 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ment the supervision of gas and electric companies. The 
 three park commissioners have been formed into a board 
 with powers of general regulation, but each commissioner 
 is still assigned to a definite section of the city for his special 
 control. A single dock commissioner has been substituted 
 for the dock and ferry board. All of these officials, except 
 those subordinate to the borough presidents, are appointed 
 by the mayor, and all are salaried officers. The permanent 
 state aqueduct and rapid transit boards continue in existence. 
 
 Chicago has had since 1861 an organization of the coordi- 
 nate services of water-supply, sewers, parks, streets, river 
 and harbor and public buildings, at first under an elected 
 board, changed in 1867 to an appointive board, and in 1876 
 changed again to a single commissioner of public works ap- 
 pointed by the mayor. As now organized, there are six 
 bureaus in the department, the heads of which are appointed 
 by the commissioner of public works. The city engineer 
 has charge of bridges and viaducts, the harbor improve- 
 ments, and the waterworks; the superintendent of streets 
 attends to paving and scavenging; the water bureau to the 
 collection of revenue for the use of water; and the remaining 
 bureaus to the sewerage system, special assessments, maps 
 and plats, and track elevation. But independent of the 
 department of public works, and indeed independent of the 
 city corporation, are the board of trustees for the sanitary 
 district, elected by popular vote, and the three park boards, 
 two appointed by the governor of the state, and one by the 
 judges of the circuit court. 
 
 Philadelphia has organized most of the municipal public 
 works into a single department. At the head of this depart- 
 ment is the director of public works, appointed by the mayor 
 subject to confirmation by the select council, who receives 
 a salary of $10,000 a year, and holds office for four years, or 
 until his successor is appointed, unless removed for cause. 
 Within this department there are seven bureaus: highways, 
 lighting, street cleaning, surveys, water, gas and city ice
 
 PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION 167 
 
 boats. The chiefs of these bureaus, with one exception, 
 are appointed by the director of public works, subject to con- 
 firmation by the select council. The chief inspector of gas 
 meters, however, is appointed by the mayor. The salaries 
 of these bureau chiefs vary widely. The highest is the chief 
 engineer of surveys, who receives $8000 a year; the chief 
 of the water bureau, $6000 ; the chief inspector of gas meters 
 has $5000; the chief of the highways bureau, $4000; the 
 chief of the street-cleaning bureau, $2500; the chief of the 
 bureau of lighting, $2000, and the superintendent of the 
 city ice boats, $1650. Each bureau is managed directly by 
 its own chief, under the supervision of the director of public 
 works. But there is provided a board of highway super- 
 visors, composed of the bureau chiefs concerned in works 
 which cause breaks in the street surface, to systematize that 
 work so as to prevent unnecessary openings and reduce 
 expenses. 
 
 There are, however, two other administrative bureaus 
 engaged in public works which are very largely independent 
 of the department and officials just mentioned. One of these 
 is the park board, composed of ten unpaid members appointed 
 by the judges of the court of common pleas, and six ex-officio 
 members, as follows: the mayor, the presidents of the select 
 and common councils, and the chiefs of the water bureau, 
 the survey bureau, and the bureau of city property. The 
 other is the harbor board, composed of the chief of the bureau 
 of surveys and six members appointed by the presidents of 
 the select and common councils. 
 
 In Boston the public works of the city are, to a large extent, 
 organized under a single department; but there are some 
 independent bureaus, while the various boards for the works 
 of interest to the larger metropolitan community increase 
 the element of disorganization. The city superintendent 
 of streets has control over paving, bridges, ferries, street 
 cleaning, and sewers, with subordinate bureaus for each class 
 of work. But the water commissioner is an independent
 
 168 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 official, as are also the board of street openings, the park 
 board, and the rapid transit board, which has charge of the 
 construction of subways and tunnels. The last-named board 
 is, moreover, appointed by the state governor. For the 
 more extensive metropolitan works, there have been three 
 boards, each appointed by the governor; in 1901 the water 
 and sewerage boards were consolidated, but the metropolitan 
 park board is still an entirely separate authority. 
 
 Baltimore has a board of public improvements, with general 
 control over all public works except the parks, which are 
 under the control of a board of five unsalaried members. 
 The board of public improvements is composed of the city 
 engineer, the inspector of buildings, and the presidents of 
 the water and harbor boards, who are all salaried officials. 
 In addition to their salaried presidents the water and harbor 
 boards have each four unpaid members. 
 
 All of the branches of municipal public works in St. Louis 
 have been organized into a definite system, although on some- 
 what different lines from the partial organization in Phila- 
 delphia. There is here a board of public improvements, 
 consisting of a president elected by popular vote, and five 
 commissioners appointed by the mayor, each of whom is 
 assigned to a special division corresponding to the bureaus 
 in the Philadelphia organization. Thus there is a street 
 commissioner, controlling the construction, repair, and clean- 
 ing of streets, a sewer commissioner, a water commissioner, 
 a harbor and wharf commissioner, and a park commissioner. 
 Provision is also made for a gas commissioner, if the city 
 should at any time own and operate municipal gas works. 
 The board prepares plans for construction works for sub- 
 mission to the municipal assembly, and enters into contracts 
 for the works to be undertaken. The president presides at 
 the meetings of the board, and has supervision over the vari- 
 ous commissioners. He receives a salary of $5000 a year. 
 The salaries of the commissioners range from $4500 to 
 $3000 each.
 
 PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION 169 
 
 The administrative arrangements in Cincinnati also bring 
 under one general control all the public works, except the 
 construction of a new system of waterworks. This authority 
 is the board of public service, composed of five elected 
 members, none of whom, however, have charge of any par- 
 ticular services, as do the members of the St. Louis board. 
 Under this board are the chief engineer (with divisions in 
 this department for highways, bridges, sewers, sidewalks, 
 and street repairs), the waterworks engineer, the superin- 
 tendent of parks, and the city electrician, and also two depart- 
 ments not often combined with public works, the health 
 department and the city hospital. The construction of the 
 new system of waterworks is under the management of an 
 independent board of five trustees. In other Ohio cities there 
 are similar elective boards of public service. 
 
 We may now turn to a considerable group of cities where 
 there is a complete organization on a distinctly similar plan. 
 This group consists of the cities of the second class in New 
 York and Pennsylvania : Pittsburg, Allegheny, Rochester, 
 Syracuse, Albany, Troy, and Scranton. In each of these 
 cities there is at the head of the whole field of municipal 
 public works a single official, known in the New York cities 
 as the commissioner of public works, and in the other cities 
 as the director of public works. In each case, too, this official 
 is appointed by the mayor of the city. The jurisdiction 
 of this officer extends in all of these cities over the streets, 
 sewers, bridges, wharves, parks, waterworks, and public 
 buildings of the city. The subordinate bureaus in this general 
 department of public works naturally show variations of 
 detail in the different cities, but all are characterized by the 
 system of single officials at the head of each bureau. In the 
 four New York cities there is a city engineer appointed by 
 the mayor, and a superintendent of waterworks and a super- 
 intendent of parks, appointed by the commissioner of public 
 works. In Pittsburg there are eight bureaus; engineering 
 and construction, surveys, highways, and sewers, city prop-
 
 170 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 erty, water-supply, water rents, public lighting, and parks. 
 Similar concentrated departments of public works under a 
 single salaried director existed for a number of years in 
 Cleveland and Columbus ; but these were replaced by boards 
 of public service under the Ohio municipal code of 1902. 
 
 Buffalo and Milwaukee are typical cities representing 
 another system of administration. In each of these cities 
 there is a salaried board of public works and a park board 
 of unsalaried members. In Buffalo the board of public 
 works consists of one elected and two appointed members, 
 each receiving a salary of $5000, under which are bureaus of 
 engineering, waterworks, streets, and building. In this case 
 the members of the board act only collectively, and the chiefs 
 of the subordinate bureaus are selected by the board. The 
 harbor master is independent of the board of public works, 
 and the park board consists of the mayor and fifteen unpaid 
 members. The Milwaukee board of public works consists 
 of three members, each of whom has a salary of $4000, one 
 of whom is the city engineer. Subordinate to this board 
 are the superintendent of bridges, the superintendent of 
 sewers, the waterworks, and the harbor master. The park 
 board has five unpaid members appointed by the mayor. 
 
 Newark and Providence have each a board of public works 
 with powers similar to those in Buffalo, while the Providence 
 park board and Essex County park commission control the 
 parks of these cities. 
 
 San Francisco and Indianapolis have each similar sets of 
 officials a board of public works and a park board. But 
 as the waterworks in these cities are owned by private com- 
 panies, the functions of the board of public works do not in- 
 clude that service. St. Paul has a salaried board of public 
 works and an unpaid park board with functions similar to 
 those authorities in San Francisco; and in addition there is 
 a board of five water commissioners, the president of which 
 receives a salary of $1000 a year, and the other members 
 $100 each.
 
 PUBLIC WORKS ADMINISTRATION 171 
 
 Until the spring of 1901 the Detroit system resembled that 
 of St. Paul, with the addition of another board for the munici- 
 pal electric light plant. But in May of that year single com- 
 missioners were provided in place of two of the boards. The 
 commissioner of public works has control over the streets, 
 sewers, wharves, bridges, and public buildings. The parks 
 are also under a single salaried commissioner. There is also a 
 water board and a lighting commission with five and six mem- 
 bers, none of whom receive salaries. These four authorities 
 remain entirely independent, with no organization for official 
 cooperation. 
 
 Other cities can generally be classed with some of the sys- 
 tems already described, and as it would serve little purpose 
 to take them up in detail, a few examples will indicate the 
 methods in less important cities. Seattle resembles St. 
 Louis, with a board of public works composed of three bureau 
 chiefs, covering all branches. Grand Rapids has a board 
 of public works with similar functions to those in Buffalo 
 and Milwaukee. Reading, like St. Paul, has three boards 
 for public works, water-supply, and parks. Worcester and 
 Cambridge have water and park boards, with single com- 
 missioners for other departments of public works. 
 
 Amid all this variety and confusion, it may yet be noticed 
 that the tendency toward system and order is strongly in 
 one direction. The only considerable group of important 
 cities with substantially similar methods includes most of 
 those cities which have accomplished a complete organiza- 
 tion of the different branches of public works into a harmo- 
 nious system. This is the group of New York and Pennsyl- 
 vania cities, with a system of single-headed bureaus under 
 the general control of a single director of public works ap- 
 pointed by the mayor of the city. The other complete sys- 
 tems of organization are those of St. Louis and Ohio cities, 
 the one grouping the bureau chiefs into a general board of 
 public improvements, the other establishing a board outside 
 of the bureau chiefs, which takes the place of the single direc-
 
 172 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 tor. But these board systems diffuse responsibility and 
 impose hindrances to prompt action, while the advantages 
 of cooperative action between various bureaus can be at 
 least as well secured through reports and recommendations 
 to a common superior as through the consultations of bureau 
 chiefs. It is indeed difficult to see wherein the arguments 
 for a single head are any less strong in considering the central 
 management of public works than they are in reference to 
 the subordinate bureaus or to the mayor as the head of the 
 entire municipal administration. 
 
 As to the control over the particular branches of public 
 work, the strongest objection to the universal application 
 of the single-commissioner system will come from those who 
 believe in the unpaid boards, especially those which control 
 the public parks. The reply must be that the management 
 of public parks, like that of street paving or sewer construc- 
 tion, is essentially a technical service, that those who accept 
 gratuitous positions cannot have any adequate special train- 
 ing; that they are never expected to devote their whole 
 time, even while in office, to their official duties; and that 
 they cannot be held to strict account for their performance. 
 The execution of details must be left to subordinates, and 
 the supervision of these details can be better secured by the 
 constant attention of a single official than by the occasional 
 meetings of men engaged in other occupations. Where 
 non-technical advice given from purely philanthropic motives 
 can be of service, it can be better secured by means of an 
 advisory board not burdened with any details of manage- 
 ment. 
 
 The system of bi-partisan boards adopted sometimes as 
 a method of securing non-partisan administration, shows a 
 curious confusion of two fundamentally different ideas; 
 and the inevitable result of -such a system is to make it impos- 
 sible to locate responsibility for the administration.
 
 X 
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS OF AMERICAN AND FOREIGN 
 
 CITIES * 
 
 THE purpose of this report is to give a bird's-eye view of 
 the local finances of the leading cities of America and Europe. 
 To this end, five European cities namely, London, Paris, 
 Berlin, Vienna, and Glasgow have been selected; also 
 the five largest cities of the United States New York, 
 Chicago, Philadelphia, St. Louis, and Boston; and also 
 the Canadian type represented in Toronto. A series of tables 
 has been prepared to show, in a comparative way, the receipts, 
 expenditures, and debt of all these cities. A number of 
 comparisons have been made with a view of bringing out 
 more distinctly the salient features of the local systems of 
 finance. There follows a description of the revenue systems 
 of these municipalities, designed to make more clear the 
 different local plans. 
 
 As a basis for comparison, there is first presented a series of 
 tables on revenue, expenditure, and debt. Table I gives the 
 ordinary revenue of New York, Philadelphia, St. Louis, and 
 Boston for the year 1903, and of Chicago for 1904. Revenues 
 are classified, following the census scheme, as "general," 
 under which head is included taxes, licenses, and state grants ; 
 and "commercial," under which is included revenue from 
 municipal industries, public-service privileges, departmental 
 receipts, and special assessments. Table II gives similar 
 figures for London, Paris, Berlin, Vienna, and Glasgow. 
 Table III gives the "ordinary" expenses (for maintenance 
 
 1 By Chas. E. Merriam and John A. Fairlie. Reprinted from Report 
 on the Municipal Revenues of Chicago, to the City Club of Chicago, 1906. 
 
 173
 
 174 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and operation) of the five leading American cities. These 
 expenditures are classified under ten main heads: "General 
 Administration," "Public Health and Safety," "Charities 
 and Corrections," "Streets," "Education," "Recreation," 
 "Miscellaneous General," "Interest," "Loans Repaid," and 
 "Municipal Industries." Under several of these main head- 
 ings subdivisions have been made. Table IV gives the 
 "extraordinary" expenses of the five largest cities of the 
 United States. These expenditures correspond roughly to 
 capital outlay by a private corporation. Tables V and VI 
 give similar figures regarding ordinary and extraordinary 
 expenditures for the European cities. Table VII presents 
 a comparison between the debts and assets of the five Ameri- 
 can cities discussed. Table VIII gives the debt of foreign 
 cities. Table IX gives the total tax rate, tax rate for local 
 purposes, local tax per capita, revenue per capita, debt per 
 capita, valuation per capita, area, street mileage, and popu- 
 lation of the five largest American cities. 
 
 It should be noted that under "Chicago" are included the 
 revenues and expenditures of all the taxing bodies lying 
 wholly within the limits of the city, and a proportionate 
 share of the county and sanitary district. As 95 per cent 
 of the valuation of the sanitary district lies within the city, 
 95 per cent of its expenses and revenues are included under 
 "Chicago," and on the same basis 92 per cent of the expenses 
 and revenues of Cook County are included. 
 
 TABLE I 
 ORDINARY REVENUES OF AMERICAN CITIES * 
 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 CHICAGO 
 
 PHILADEL- 
 PHIA 
 
 ST. Louis 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 Taxes . . . 
 
 Licenses, forfei- 
 tures, fines 
 State grants . 
 Miscellaneous 
 
 General . . 
 
 $76,296,721 
 
 7,469,152 
 1,306,225 
 275,722 
 
 $21,469,607 
 
 4,513,915 
 306,840 
 231,098 
 
 $18,415,082 
 
 2,103,234 
 910,987 
 155,551 
 
 $9,456,773 
 
 1,669,949 
 202,251 
 59,901 
 
 $18,439,775 
 
 1,229,351 
 12,100 
 179,520 
 
 $ 85,347,820 
 
 $26,521,460 
 
 $21,584,854 
 
 $11,388,871 
 
 $19,860,746 
 
 1 This does not include in any case receipts from loans or other extraordinary 
 revenues.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 
 
 175 
 
 TABLE I. Continued 
 ORDINARY REVENUES OF AMERICAN CITIES 
 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 CHICAGO 
 
 PHILADEL- 
 PHIA 
 
 ST. Louis 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 Municipal indus- 
 tries . 
 Public - service 
 privileges 
 Departmental re- 
 ceipts . . 
 Special assess- 
 ments 
 
 Commercial 
 
 $13,036,497 
 712,410 
 1,110,684 
 6,935,531 
 
 $5,072,666 
 513,763 
 2,015,401 
 4,298,684 
 
 $6,073,029 
 113,574 
 1,127,123 
 710,077 
 
 $2,173,037 
 266,439 
 518,622 
 3,261,143 
 
 $3,121,485 
 83,466 
 586,655 
 413,740 
 
 $21,785,122 
 
 $11,900,514 
 
 $8,023,803 
 
 $6,219,241 
 
 $4,205,346 
 
 Total . . 
 
 $107,132,942 
 
 $38,421,974 
 
 $29,618,657 
 
 $17,808,112 
 
 $24,066,092 
 
 Per capita 
 General . 
 Commercial 
 
 Total . . 
 
 $22.97 
 5.86 
 
 $13.73 
 6.15 
 
 $15.78 
 5.87 
 
 $18.60 
 10.16 
 
 $33.40 
 7.07 
 
 $28.83 
 
 $19.88 
 
 $21.65 
 
 $28.76 
 
 $40.47 
 
 TABLE II 
 ORDINARY REVENUES OF EUROPEAN CITIES 
 
 
 LONDON, 
 1902-3 
 
 PARIS, 
 1902 
 
 BERLIN, 
 1901-2 
 
 VIENNA, 
 1S02 
 
 GLASGOW, 
 1901-2 
 
 Direct taxes . 
 Indirect taxes, 
 licenses, 
 fines . 
 State grants . 
 Miscellaneous 
 
 General . . 
 
 $69,175,000 
 
 1,025,000 
 11,781,000 
 2,206,000 
 
 $20,592,000 
 
 21,901,000 
 4,374,000 
 520,000 
 
 $15,190,000 1 
 
 757,000 
 6,477,000 
 54,000 
 
 $11,874,000 
 
 2,960,000 
 4,560,000 
 180,000 
 
 $7,064,000 
 
 176,000 
 1,960,000 
 
 $84,187,000 
 
 $47,387,000 
 
 $22,478,000 
 
 $19,574,000 
 
 $9,200,000 
 
 Municipal in- 
 dustries . 
 Public-service 
 privileges 
 Departmental 
 receipts . 
 
 $8,503,000 
 398,000 
 2,597,000 
 
 $9,363,000 
 6,713,000 
 4,820,000 
 
 $11,782,000 
 1,160,000 
 4,760,000 
 
 $10,089,000 
 231,000 
 
 $9,830,000 
 885,000 
 
 Special assess- 
 ments 
 
 Commercial 
 
 1,947,000 
 
 
 1,758,000 
 
 3,216,000 
 
 90,000 
 
 $13,445,000 
 
 $20,896,000 
 
 $19,460,000 
 
 $13,536,000 
 
 $10,805,000 
 
 Total . . 
 
 $97,632,000 
 
 $68,283,000 
 
 $41,938,000 
 
 $33,110,000 
 
 $20,005,000 
 
 Population . 
 Per capita 
 General 
 Commercial 
 
 Total . . 
 
 4,560,000 
 
 $18.44 
 2.97 
 
 2,659,000 
 
 $17.82 
 7.86 
 
 1,888,326 
 
 $11.90 
 10.30 
 
 1,674,957 
 
 $11.65 
 8.75 
 
 912,000 
 
 $10.90 
 11.85 
 
 $21.41 
 
 $25.68 
 
 $22.20 
 
 $20.40 
 
 $22.75 
 
 Sec. Ill, p. 206.
 
 176 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 TABLE III 
 ORDINARY EXPENDITURES OF AMERICAN CITIES 
 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 CHICAGO 
 
 PHILA- 
 DELPHIA 
 
 ST. Louis 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 General adminis- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 tration 
 
 $6,840,552 
 
 $2,353,933 
 
 $2,101,161 
 
 $780,282 
 
 $1,320,522 
 
 Courts . 
 Police . . . 
 Fire. . . . 
 Health . . . 
 Public health 
 and safety 
 
 $3,434,213 
 12,581,332 
 5,850,807 
 1,271,652 
 
 $860,352 
 4,014,713 
 1,920,244 
 191,220 
 
 $564,566 
 3,208,910 
 1,225,807 
 346,215 
 
 $407,689 
 1,614,091 
 862,429 
 146,270 
 
 $717,137 
 1,849,213 
 1,314,509 
 188,183 
 
 $25,524,584 
 
 $7,162,282 
 
 $5,918,828 
 
 $3,187,812 
 
 $4,409,590 
 
 Charities and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 corrections 
 
 $6,277,065 
 
 $1,600,574 
 
 $1,300,051 
 
 $661,079 
 
 $1,844,670 
 
 Street-cleaning 
 and refuse- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 disposal . 
 Street-lighting 
 Sewers . 
 Miscellaneous 
 
 $6,148,087 
 1,644,417 
 778,391 
 
 $1,205,197 
 349,237 
 412,142 
 
 $1,207,338 
 1,357,327 
 120,492 
 
 $814,564 
 504,238 
 139,610 
 
 $1,047,094 
 776,562 
 334,156 
 
 streets 
 Streets and 
 
 2,976,440 
 
 405,432 
 
 1,126,468 
 
 746,723 
 
 1,179,402 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 sewers . . 
 
 $11,493,216 
 
 $2,785,002 
 
 $3,811,629 
 
 $2,205,135 
 
 $3,255,505 
 
 Schools . . . 
 Libraries . 
 
 Education . 
 Recreation 
 
 $21,804,610 
 1,118,705 
 
 $8,419,127 
 178,666 
 
 $4,242,710 
 279,344 
 
 $2,015,299 
 67,755 
 
 $3,588,212 
 280,166 
 
 $22,923,375 
 
 $8,597,793 
 
 $4,522,054 
 
 $2,083,054 
 
 $3,868,378 
 
 $1,514,644 
 
 $665,403 
 
 $561,308 
 
 $160,280 
 
 $645,009 
 
 Miscellaneous 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 general 
 Total general 
 
 $51,520 
 
 $91,128 
 
 $43,250 
 
 $15,903 
 
 $741,672 
 
 $74,624,956 
 
 $23,256,115 
 
 $18,258,543 
 
 $9,093,645 
 
 $15,085,346 
 
 Interest . . 
 Loans repaid 
 Municipal indus- 
 tries . 
 
 Total ordi- 
 
 $12,289,489 
 12,511,634 
 
 6,069,537 
 
 $1,563,713 
 3,314,810 
 
 2,073,955 
 
 $1,683,709 
 3,071,300 
 
 2,035,831 
 
 $945,008 
 191,090 
 
 897,019 
 
 $3,390,142 
 5,219,574 
 
 1,446,760 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 nary . . 
 
 $105,505,616 
 
 $30,208,693 
 
 $25,049,383 
 
 $11,126,762 
 
 $25,141,812 
 
 Extraordinary 
 Grand total 
 
 64,422,050 
 
 12,075,545 
 
 13,369,332 
 
 5,364,123 
 
 8,827,482 
 
 $169,927,666 
 
 $42,284,238 
 
 $38,418,715 
 
 $16,490,885 
 
 $33,969,294 
 
 Per capita 
 General . 
 Total ordinary 
 
 $20.08 
 28.39 
 
 12.03 
 .15.63 
 
 13.35 
 18.03 
 
 14.52 
 18.17 
 
 25.37 
 42.45
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 
 
 177 
 
 TABLE IV 
 EXTRAORDINARY EXPENDITURES (OUTLAYS) OF AMERICAN CITIES 
 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 CHICAGO 
 
 PHILA- 
 DELPHIA 
 
 ST. Louis 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 General adminis- 
 tration 
 Public safety 
 Charities and 
 correction 
 Streets and 
 sewers 
 Education 
 Recreation 
 
 General . 
 
 Municipal indus- 
 tries . 
 
 Total . . 
 
 $1,212,787 
 1,108,373 
 
 670,270 
 
 19,649,546 
 7,432,903 
 7,146,274 
 
 $736,333 
 27,991 
 
 537,028 
 
 4,898,948 
 1,544,770 
 3,015,936 
 
 $8,158 
 617,465 
 
 181,511 
 
 4,797,330 
 1,044,486 
 592,418 
 
 $62,746 
 158,767 
 
 207,704 
 
 3,577,433 
 855,639 
 7,354 
 
 $66,746 
 23,004 
 
 559,808 
 
 5,317,103 
 
 1,476,415 
 250,076 
 
 $37,220,153 
 27,201,897 
 
 $10,776,727 
 1,297,918 
 
 $7,241,368 
 6,127,964 
 
 $4,869,643 
 494,480 
 
 $7,693,152 
 1,158,643 
 
 $64,422,050 
 
 $12,075,545 
 
 $13,369,332 
 
 $5,364,123 
 
 $8,827,482 
 
 TABLE V 
 ORDINARY EXPENDITURES OF EUROPEAN CITIES 
 
 
 LONDON 
 1902-3 
 
 PARIS 
 1902 
 
 BERLIN 
 1901-2 
 
 VIENNA 
 1902 
 
 GLASGOW 
 1901-2 
 
 General adminis- 
 tration 
 
 Courts . 
 Police . 
 Fire department 
 Health dep't . 
 Public health 
 and safety 
 
 Charities . 
 Correction . 
 Charities and 
 correction 
 
 Miscel. streets 
 Street cleaning 
 and refuse- 
 disposal . 
 Street lighting 
 Sewers . 
 
 Streets and 
 sewers 
 
 $5,239,000 
 
 $1,147,000 
 8,764,000 
 1,038,000 
 760,000 
 
 $771,000 
 
 $620,000 
 6,821,000 
 706,000 
 268,000 
 
 $3,055,000 
 
 $1,780,000 
 5,397,000 
 503,000 
 135,000 
 
 $2,992,000 
 
 $1,300,000 
 2,075,000 
 263,000 
 39,000 
 
 $153,000 
 
 $200,000 
 765,000 
 114,000 
 294,000 
 
 $11,709,000 
 
 $20,862,000 
 1,990,000 
 
 $8,415,000 
 
 $10,988,000 
 442,000 
 
 $7,815,000 
 
 $4,955,000 
 300,000 
 
 $3,677,000 
 
 $2,920,000 
 300,000 
 
 $1,373,000 
 
 $1,578,000 
 200,000 
 
 $21,852,000 
 $10,097,000 
 
 1,775,000 
 1,980,000 
 2,156,000 
 
 $11,430,000 
 $4,145,000 
 
 2,350,000 
 1,785,000 
 1,343,000 
 
 $5,255,000 
 $384,000 
 
 999,000 
 85,000 
 1,288,000 
 
 $3,220,000 
 $1,738,000 
 
 758,000 
 122,000 
 422,000 
 
 $1,778,000 
 $346,000 
 
 692,000 
 528,000 
 136,000 
 
 $16,008,000 
 
 $9,623,000 
 
 $2,756,000 
 
 $3,040,000 
 
 $1,702,000
 
 178 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 TABLE V (Continued) 
 
 
 LONDON 
 1902-3 
 
 PARIS 
 1902 
 
 BERLIN 
 1901-2 
 
 VIENNA 
 
 1902 
 
 GLASGOW 
 1901-2 
 
 Schools . . . 
 Libraries, etc. 
 
 Education . 
 
 Parks. . . . 
 Baths, etc. . . 
 
 Recreation . 
 Miscel. general 
 Total general 
 
 Interest . . . 
 Loans repaid . 
 Municipal indus- 
 tries . . 
 
 Total ordinary 
 Extraordinary 
 
 Grand total 
 
 Per capita 
 General . . 
 Total ordinary 
 
 $13,713,000 
 697,000 
 
 $7,127,000 
 633,000 
 
 $7,078,000 
 48,000 
 
 $5,942,000 
 41,000 
 
 $1,960,000 
 32,000 
 
 $14,410,000 
 
 $1,266,000 
 780,000 
 
 $7,760,000 
 $600,000 
 
 $7,126,000 
 
 $456,000 
 94,000 
 
 $5,983,000 
 
 $504,000 
 72,000 
 
 $1,992,000 
 
 $235,000 
 91,000 
 
 $2,046,000 
 $2,446,000 
 
 $600,000 
 $1,785,000 
 
 $550,000 
 $227,000 
 
 $576,000 
 $676,000 
 
 $326,000 
 $525,000 
 
 $73,710,000 
 
 $10,142,000 
 6,821,000 
 
 4,646,000 
 
 $45,385,000 
 
 $16,000,000 
 6,475,000 
 
 2,120,000 
 
 $26,784,000 
 
 $2,614,000 
 1,710,000 
 
 7,560,000 
 
 $20,164,000 
 
 $3,197,000 
 1,400,000 
 
 4,553,000 
 
 $7,850,000 
 
 $2,412,000 
 1,571,000 
 
 7,422,000 
 
 $95,319,000 
 39,071,000 
 
 $69,980,000 
 10,630,000 
 
 $38,668,000 
 10,897,000 
 
 $29,314,000 
 28,912,000 
 
 $19,255,000 
 6,496,000 
 
 $134,390,000 
 
 $16.17 
 20.47 
 
 $80,610,000 
 
 $17.08 
 26.31 
 
 $49,565,000 
 
 $14.24 
 20.35 
 
 $58,226,000 
 
 $12.24 
 17.24 
 
 $25,751,000 
 
 $8.61 
 21.11 
 
 ORDINARY EXPENDITURES, MUNICIPAL INDUSTRIES 
 
 Real estate and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 buildings . 
 
 $216,000 
 
 $53,000 
 
 $67,000 
 
 $80,000 
 
 $389,000 
 
 Waterworks . 
 
 
 1,360,000 
 
 688,000 
 
 325,000 
 
 314,000 
 
 Gas-works . . 
 
 
 
 5,526,000 
 
 2,424,000 
 
 3,492,000 
 
 Electric lighting 
 
 704,000 
 
 
 
 267,000 
 
 312,000 
 
 Markets and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 abattoirs . 
 
 623,000 
 
 360,000 
 
 1,204,000 
 
 956,000 
 
 148,000 
 
 Cemeteries . . 
 
 325,000 
 
 347,000 
 
 12,000 
 
 157,000 
 
 1.000 
 
 Street railways 
 
 1,990,000 
 
 
 
 
 2,713,000 
 
 
 
 
 
 Ins. 
 
 Tel. 
 
 Docks and har- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 bors . . 
 
 788,000 
 
 
 63,000 
 
 344,000 
 
 53,000 
 
 Municipal prop- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 erty and in- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 dustries . 
 
 $4,646,000 
 
 $2,120,000 
 
 $7,560,000 
 
 $4,553,000 
 
 $7,422,000
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 
 
 179 
 
 TABLE VI 
 EXTRAORDINARY EXPENDITURES OF EUROPEAN CITIES 
 
 
 LONDON 
 
 PARIS 
 
 BERLIN 
 
 VIENNA 
 
 GLASGOW 
 
 General adminis- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 tration 
 
 $294,000 
 
 $23,000 
 
 $1,597,000 
 
 $778,000 
 
 $281,000 
 
 Public health and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 safety . . 
 
 427,000 
 
 323,000 
 
 
 43,000 
 
 100,000 
 
 Charities and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 correction 
 
 6,690,000 
 
 378,000 
 
 
 468,000 
 
 457,000 
 
 Streets and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 sewers . . 
 
 18,100,000 
 
 1,929,000 
 
 4,406,000 
 
 1,491,000 
 
 1,127,000 
 
 Education . . 
 
 3,454,000 
 
 639,000 
 
 1,280,000 
 
 305,000 
 
 411,700 
 
 Recreation . . 
 
 1,070,000 
 
 150,000 
 
 
 108,000 
 
 200,400 
 
 Municipal indus- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 tries . . 
 
 8,600,000 
 
 6,023,000 
 
 3,614,000 
 
 25,124,000 
 
 3,701,000 
 
 Miscellaneous . 
 
 436,000 
 
 1,165,000 
 
 
 595,000 
 
 219,000 
 
 Total . . . 
 
 $39,071,000 
 
 $10,630,000 
 
 $10,897,000 
 
 $28,912,000 
 
 $6,496,000 
 
 TABLE VII 
 DEBTS AND ASSETS OF AMERICAN CITIES 
 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 CHICAGO 
 
 PHILADEL- 
 PHIA 
 
 ST. Louis 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 Total Debt 
 Total less 
 sinking- 
 fund 
 
 assets 
 
 $532,977,235 
 381,687,512 
 
 $51,204,532 
 49,901,932 
 
 $58,383,532 
 50,654,640 
 
 $24,077,474 
 22,579,917 
 
 $120,152,106 
 92,096,663 
 
 Per capita 
 Assets . . 
 Salable and 
 produc- 
 tive . 
 Salable and 
 
 $102.68 
 $129,632,268 
 
 $25.82 
 $63,453,496 
 
 $37.04 
 $110,109,530 
 
 $36.86 
 $21,408,347 
 
 $154.88 
 $20,613,219 
 
 unpro- 
 ductive 
 
 Total . 
 
 394,456,470 
 
 163,789,120 
 
 88,345,156 
 
 20,764,580 
 
 91,176,775 
 
 $524,088,738 
 
 $227,242,616 
 
 $198,554,686 
 
 $42,172,927 
 
 $111,789,994 
 
 TABLE VIII 
 DEBT OF FOREIGN CITIES 
 
 
 LONDON 
 
 PARIS 
 
 BERLIN 
 
 VIENNA 
 
 GLASGOW 
 
 Debt . . 
 Per capita 
 
 $335,492,000 
 $73.57 
 
 $459,530,000 
 $172.82 
 
 $59,230,000 
 $31.36 
 
 $97,399,000 
 $58.02 
 
 $78,620,000 
 $86.20
 
 180 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 TABLE IX 
 
 
 TAX RATE 
 
 TAX RATE 
 
 LOCAL TAX 
 
 TOTAL LOCAL 
 
 DEBT 
 
 
 FOR ALL 
 
 FOR LOCAL 
 
 PER 
 
 REVENUE 
 
 PER 
 
 
 PURPOSES 
 
 PURPOSES 
 
 CAPITA 
 
 PER CAPITA 
 
 CAPITA 
 
 Boston 
 
 $7.40 
 
 $7.40 
 
 $30.78 
 
 $40.47 
 
 $154.88 
 
 
 ( 7.06 
 
 6.995 ) 
 
 
 
 
 New York . . 
 
 < to 
 ( 7.48 
 
 to [ 
 7.415 J 
 
 20.53 
 
 28.83 
 
 102.68 
 
 St. Louis . 
 
 10.95 
 
 10.10 
 
 15.44 
 
 28.76 
 
 36.86 
 
 Philadelphia 
 
 7.50 2 
 
 7.50 
 
 13.46 
 
 21.65 
 
 37.04 
 
 
 ( 5.75 
 
 5.20 I 
 
 
 
 
 Chicago . . . 
 
 to 
 ( 6.59 
 
 to V 
 6.04 ) 
 
 11.11 
 
 19.88 
 
 25.82 
 
 
 VALUATION 
 PER CAPITA 
 
 AREA, 
 ACRES 
 
 STREETS, 
 MILES 
 
 POPULATION 
 
 Boston 
 
 $2,054.68 
 
 27,532 
 
 500 
 
 594,618 
 
 New York 
 
 1,461.84 
 
 209,218 
 
 2,589 
 
 3,716,139 
 
 St. Louis 
 Philadelphia 
 
 724.92 
 978.17 
 
 39,276 
 81,833 
 
 1,004 
 1,661 
 
 612,279 
 1,367,716 
 
 Chicago 
 
 1,097.80 
 
 114,932 
 
 4,235 
 
 1,932,315 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 A payment of $900,000 for state taxes is made from this. 
 
 ' 7.50 on real estate; 2.20 on personalty-extensive corporation taxes. Down to 1904 
 the rate was 9.25. All tax-rates are estimated on the basis of a one-fifth valuation, as 
 in Chicago. 
 
 SECTION I. GENERAL COMPARISONS 
 
 Comparing the revenues of American cities, it appears that 
 the per capita income of Chicago is smaller than that of any 
 other great city, American or European. On the Philadelphia 
 basis its revenue would be about $3,000,000 greater than at 
 present; on the New York or St. Louis basis, about $18,000,000 
 larger; on the Boston basis, about double the amount now 
 received. In "commercial revenue" Chicago compares 
 favorably with the other great cities, but in "general 
 revenue" the deficiency is most clearly evident. Chicago's 
 $13.73 per capita of general revenue is far behind the $33.40 
 of Boston, the $22.97 of New York, the $18.60 of St. Louis, 
 and is considerably below the $15.78 of Philadelphia. A 
 closer analysis of the situation shows that Chicago's greatest 
 weakness lies in the tax revenue per capita. In licenses,
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 181 
 
 fines, and forfeitures, Chicago, with a per capita income of 
 $2.24, stands second to St. Louis, with $2.55; while Boston 
 obtains $1.93, New York $1.73, and Philadelphia $1.56, 
 respectively. In this respect, then, the revenue of Chicago 
 compares favorably with that of other American cities. In 
 revenue from taxes, however, Chicago lags far behind the 
 others of its group. Boston raises $30.78 per capita by taxes ; 
 New York, $20.53; St. Louis, $15.44; Philadelphia, $13.46; 
 while Chicago contributes only $11.11. On the Philadelphia 
 basis, Chicago's revenue from taxes for local purposes would 
 be $4,000,000 greater than at present; estimated on the St. 
 Louis basis, its revenue would be about $8,000,000 larger; 
 on the New York basis, its revenue would be increased 
 about $18,000,000; and, finally, on the Boston basis the 
 local revenue from taxes would be increased almost three 
 times. So far as per capita figures go, it appears that the 
 weakest spot in the local revenue system of Chicago is the 
 small amount of taxes paid for local purposes. 
 
 Comparing the revenue of Chicago with that of European 
 cities, it is found that the local income is below that of any 
 city considered, without exception. The revenue of Paris 
 is about $5 per capita greater; that of London, Berlin, and 
 Glasgow, about $2 greater. On the Paris basis, its revenue 
 would be about $10,000,000 larger than at present; on the 
 basis of the other cities in question, about $3,000,000 more 
 than is now received. Such comparisons are unfair, however, 
 since they disregard the difference in the purchasing power 
 of money in European and American cities. Forty million 
 dollars will go farther in Berlin than in Chicago, not only 
 because of the method of administration, but because of the 
 different level of prices prevailing. If the incomes of Chicago 
 and Berlin were exactly equal in dollars, the purchasing 
 power of the Berlin income would be greater, and our revenues 
 would in effect be considerably smaller than theirs. 
 
 It is a fair conclusion, then, that the revenues of Chicago, 
 including not only the city, but all other local taxing bodies,
 
 182 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 are lower than those of any other of the ten largest cities of 
 Europe and America. Consequently, unless all records for 
 efficiency and economy in the expenditure of money are 
 broken, our local government must inevitably suffer in 
 comparison with that of other great metropolitan com- 
 munities. A decentralized, unsystematic, and irresponsible 
 system of local finances, operated under a bipartisan system, 
 increases the already great difficulties with which we must 
 contend. 
 
 A comparison of expenditures quickly reveals the points 
 where Chicago suffers most from lack of sufficient revenue. 
 Thus the police expenditure per capita in Chicago amounts 
 to only $2.08, as against $2.35 for Philadelphia, $2.64 for 
 St. Louis, $3.11 for Boston, and $3.39 for New York. For 
 street cleaning, Chicago expends 62 cents per capita, as against 
 89 cents for Philadelphia, $1.33 for St. Louis, $1.69 for New 
 York, and $1.78 for Boston. In such matters as police 
 protection and street cleaning the great area of Chicago 
 makes the discrepancy far larger than these figures indicate. 
 Again, for purposes of public health, Chicago contributes 
 10 cents per capita, while the expense in other cities of its 
 size ranges from 24 to 32 cents. In many other items the 
 scantiness of revenue is evident. But the scope of this in- 
 vestigation does not cover the matter of expenditure, and 
 consequently no extended analysis of such facts will be made 
 here. Examination of the tables presented will show many 
 interesting facts regarding the objects of local expenditure 
 in this country and abroad. 1 
 
 SECTION II. REVENUES OF AMERICAN CITIES 
 
 In order to make clearer the revenue systems in the United 
 States, a description is now given of the revenue machinery 
 and revenues of New York, Philadelphia, St. Louis, and 
 Boston. The revenues of each of these cities are analyzed, 
 
 1 See Census Bulletin 20, Statistics of Cities, 1902-1903, for comparative 
 statistics and a variety of questions.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 183 
 
 with special attention to their characteristic features, and 
 in addition to this, the general scheme of revenue administra- 
 tion is outlined. The underlying purpose is to show where 
 and how the local revenue system of Chicago deviates from 
 that of other great cities of the United States. 
 
 NEW YORK CITY 
 
 New York City includes within its limits four counties 
 New York, Queens, Kings, and Richmond. The finances 
 of these counties are included, however, in those of the city, 
 the various receipts of the counties being turned over to the 
 city, and appropriations for county expenses being made by 
 the city. Thus, although the county officers are not appointed 
 by, or responsible to, the city government, and the unity of 
 the local government is to this extent interfered with, the 
 financial unity is fairly complete. The city is further divided 
 into five boroughs, Manhattan, Brooklyn, Queens, the 
 Bronx, and Richmond, and a variety of local functions, 
 notably those concerning local improvements, are vested 
 in these authorities. Financial authority is, however, re- 
 tained in the hands of the city as a whole, and, except for 
 the interference of the state legislature, fiscal power in New 
 York is pretty well centralized. One central authority regu- 
 lates receipts and disbursements for the entire community. 
 This power is placed in the board of estimate and appor- 
 tionment, a body composed of the mayor, the comptroller, 
 and the president of the board of aldermen, each having 
 three votes, and the presidents of the five boroughs with 
 seven votes all together. 
 
 The revenue machinery of New York City is made up of 
 a considerable variety of administrative authorities. There 
 is, in the first place, an elective comptroller, in whose hands 
 is placed the direction of the fiscal policy of the city. Under 
 this office are five bureaus, which are concerned with (1) the 
 collection of revenue from interest on bonds and mortgages, 
 and the rents of city property; (2) the collection of taxes;
 
 184 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 (3) assessments and arrears; there is also (4) an auditing 
 bureau; and (5) the city chamberlain, or treasurer. None 
 of the officers in these bureaus is elected except the comp- 
 troller. In addition to these, there are the commissioners 
 of the sinking fund, a body composed of the mayor, the 
 comptroller, the chamberlain, the president of the board 
 of aldermen, and the chairman of the finance committee; 
 and also two commissioners of accounts, in charge of the 
 city's accounting system. 
 
 The assessment of taxes is conducted by the department 
 of taxes and assessments, a board of five members appointed 
 by the mayor ; and the revision of assessments is in the hands 
 of the comptroller, the corporation counsel, and the presi- 
 dent of the department of taxes and assessments, who 
 constitute a board of review. The collection of taxes is 
 carried on by the office of the receiver of taxes. Further- 
 more, there is a board of assessors (three at $3000), whose 
 function is to spread such special assessments as have been 
 approved. There is, in addition to these, a commissioner 
 of taxes (an appointive officer), who has nothing to do with 
 taxes at all, but does have jurisdiction over the licensing 
 and regulation of employment offices. Saloon licenses are 
 collected by the state excise commissioner, through his 
 deputies and assistants. 
 
 Taking up the principal items of revenue, we may say that 
 taxes are levied and collected by city officers, with the ex- 
 ception of the franchise tax assessed by the state board; 
 special assessments are spread by the board of assessors, 
 and collected by the department of assessments and arrears ; 
 the receipts from municipal industries, of which the most 
 important are water and docks, are collected by these de- 
 partments respectively; licenses (except saloon licenses, 
 which are collected by the state) are collected partly by the 
 bureau of licenses, and in small part by the mayor's office. 
 Street-railway and other public-service privilege revenues gen- 
 erally are under the supervision of the bureau of franchises,
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 185 
 
 but collected by the collector of city revenue. The col- 
 lector of city revenue is also responsible for the collection 
 of rentals on city property. All officers receiving money 
 must make a daily return to the office of the city chamber- 
 lain, with the exception of the county fee officers, who make 
 a monthly accounting. 
 
 It should not be inferred from this catalogue of revenue 
 officers that there is a lack of necessary centralization in New 
 York City. There are, it is true, a number of state officers 
 overlapping to some extent the local, but, as far as local 
 officers are concerned, there is no such difficulty. The city 
 of New York, and the four counties of New York, Kings, 
 Queens, and Richmond, are coterminous and consolidated. 
 They have one central financial body, the board of estimate 
 and apportionment; one budget covers the expenses of all; 
 they have one treasurer: agencies of the city are found in 
 the various boroughs for purposes of collecting taxes and 
 various licenses; but the financial authority is centralized. 
 All money received passes through the hands of the city 
 chamberlain, and all expenditures pass through the board 
 of estimate and apportionment. Only a few fee officers 
 still survive as an exception to this. 
 
 A notable feature of the New York system is the attention 
 given to the auditing of revenue and expense. In addition 
 to the regular corps of auditors, consisting of one hundred 
 men, there is a department of investigation in the office of 
 the comptroller. This is made up of sixteen men, eight of 
 whom are selected for their ability as investigators, and eight 
 constitute the clerical force. The principal duty of these 
 officers is the audit of claims against the city, but they are 
 available, and are used for the purpose of making special 
 inquiries and examinations under the direction of the comp- 
 troller. Thousands of dollars are saved annually through 
 the activity of this department. In addition to this force 
 in the comptroller's office, there are under the mayor two 
 commissioners of accounts, one of whom must be a certified
 
 186 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 accountant. The work of these commissioners is to examine 
 city receipts and disbursements every three months, and also 
 to make special reports from time to time on the accounts 
 and methods of the various departments of the city govern- 
 ment. About eighty men are employed in this office. 
 
 The aggregate ordinary revenue of New York City is about 
 $107,000,000. Of this sum the largest items are taxes, 
 $76,000,000; municipal industries, $13,000,000; licenses, 
 $7,500,000; special assessments, $7,000,000; and depart- 
 mental receipts, a little over $1,000,000. 
 
 Taxes are raised on a valuation of $4,751,532,106, real 
 estate, and $680,866,092, personal property, or a total 
 of $5,432,398,198. The real-estate valuation includes the 
 franchise values of special privilege corporations, which are 
 assessed by the state and returned to the city. These fran- 
 chises were valued at $235,000,000 in 1903, and in 1904 at 
 $251,000,000. Of this latter amount $190,000,000 is found 
 in Manhattan borough alone. A decided gain in the valuation 
 of real estate has been made in recent years, notably under 
 the administration of Seth Low. The assessment of real 
 estate was raised from $2,932,000,000 in 1899 to $4,751,000,000 
 in 1903. In valuing real estate, the assessments of land 
 and improvements are placed in separate columns, and the 
 assessments published yearly in convenient sections. The 
 local tax on real and personal property is supplemented by 
 a series of state taxes on corporations. 
 
 In addition to the taxes mentioned, the law of 1902 pro- 
 vides for the assessment and taxation of bank shares. The 
 value of each share is ascertained by adding the capital 
 stock, surplus, and undivided profits, and dividing the result 
 by the number of shares outstanding. The tax of 1 per 
 cent levied on this valuation is collected by the banks and 
 returned to the receiver of taxes. In 1903 the assessed 
 valuation of such shares amounts to $266,692,116, on which 
 a tax of $2,666,000 was collected. 
 
 The tax-rate in New York City ranges from $1.41367 per
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 187 
 
 $100 in Manhattan and the Bronx to $1.49675 in Richmond. 
 Since the valuation of real estate has advanced, the tax- 
 rate has fallen from $2.4804, the rate in 1899. Practically 
 all of the tax goes to the locality, as the rate for state pur- 
 poses is only thirteen one-hundredths of a mill. 
 
 From municipal industries a revenue of about $13,000,000 
 is derived. Of this the waterworks return about $9,000,000, 
 the city docks about $3,0(30,000, city markets and other 
 property about $1,000,000. Interest on public deposits 
 amounts to $264,000 (1904). This is reckoned at the rate of 
 2 per cent on daily deposits. The average daily balance 
 runs from two to ten millions. The law provides that public 
 deposits in any given bank shall not exceed one-half of the 
 capital stock and surplus of the institution, and a list of the 
 depositaries, with the amount of interest paid by each, is 
 published annually. There are 156 depositaries of city and 
 county funds (114 banks and 42 trust companies), and 29 
 depositaries for court and trust funds, making a total of 185 
 official depositaries. 
 
 About $7,000,000 is paid in the form of special assessments. 
 These improvements are initiated in a local improvement 
 district, approved by the board of estimate and apportion- 
 ment, and then spread by the board of assessors. Assess- 
 ments are not levied for repairing or renewal, but such 
 expense is borne by the city. 
 
 The license revenue of New York City is about $7,500,000. 
 Of this the saloons pay about $6,000,000, which is one-half 
 of the total license paid by them. The balance goes to the 
 state. The rate varies from $750 in boroughs of 50,000 to 
 500,000, to $1200 in boroughs of from 500,000 to 1,500,000, 
 and is collected under the supervision of a special state officer, 
 the excise commissioner. The next largest item is that 
 of fines and forfeitures, from which $1,000,000 is obtained. 
 Other important items are receipts from pawnbrokers, 
 about $100,000; from theatrical and concert licenses, about 
 ),000; from sidewalk stands, about $25,000.
 
 188 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Departmental receipts (about $1,000,000) are derived from 
 a variety of miscellaneous sources. Of these, one of the 
 most important is the court fees of the various counties. 
 These are turned in to the city treasury monthly by the 
 respective court officers. It is to be observed that a con- 
 siderable body of trust funds is also in the hands of the 
 treasurer, and that the interest on these funds goes to the 
 city. As custodian of these court funds, the chamberlain 
 holds about $4,500,000, on which net earnings amount to 
 $133,000. 
 
 Public-service privileges are credited with $700,000 annual 
 returns. This does not include, however, the revenue from 
 the special franchises assessed and taxed as real estate. 
 From street railways about $400,000 is obtained. This is 
 based on a license of from $20 to $50 per car for some lines, 
 and for others on a percentage of the gross receipts ranging 
 from one-third of 1 per cent to 8 per cent, but which in most 
 cases is from 3 to 5 per cent. 1 Incidental revenue is derived 
 from pipe lines, tunnel and vault space, and bay-windows. 
 From gas and electric lighting companies the returns are 
 inconsiderable. The principal contribution is made by the 
 East River Gas Co., which pays $20,000, or 3 per cent of its 
 gross receipts. 
 
 By way of state grants the city receives about $1,300,000. 
 This is a grant in aid of schools and libraries, but it is partly 
 offset by the city's payment to the state for schools, in the 
 form of general state tax. 
 
 The debt of New York aggregates $532,997,235. From 
 this must be deducted sinking-fund assets, leaving the amount 
 at $381,687,512. Estimated per capita, this is a burden of 
 $102.68. If the assets of the city are figured in, however, 
 the debt is reversed to a balance in favor of New York. The 
 salable assets amount to $524,000,000, so that the city is 
 really in a prosperous condition. 
 
 The assembly of 1905 provided for two new classes of taxes, 
 
 1 See Comptroller's Report for 1902, p. 303.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 189 
 
 which are now in the experimental stage. These are a tax 
 on mortgages and a tax on stock transfers. The mortgage 
 tax is levied at a rate of five mills per dollar. It is collected 
 by the state, and one-half of the proceeds is returned to the 
 locality. The stock-transfer law of 1905 prescribes a tax 
 on stock transfers. This is imposed on "all sales, or agree- 
 ments to sell, or memoranda of sales or deliveries or transfers 
 of shares and certificates of stock in any domestic or foreign 
 association, company, or corporation." On such transfers 
 a tax of two cents per $100 is placed. Taxes so collected are 
 paid into the state treasury, and the locality has no share 
 in the revenue raised. 
 
 The conspicuous features in the revenue system of New 
 York are, then, the consolidation of local financial power in 
 the hands of the board of estimate and apportionment, the 
 taxation of franchises as real estate, the large revenue from 
 municipal industries, and the heavy payments by saloons. 
 The mortgage tax and the stock-transfer tax introduce new 
 elements into the system. The careful provision for the 
 auditing and inspection of revenues and expenditures is a 
 feature of the New York system not to be overlooked. 1 
 
 PHILADELPHIA 
 
 In Philadelphia the limits of city and county are coter- 
 minous, and the governments are practically merged into 
 a consolidated county-city. There is consequently a unified 
 management of local finances, without division of authority 
 over receipts and disbursements. The principal financial 
 authorities of Philadelphia are the comptroller, elected for 
 a term of three years; the treasurer, elected for the same 
 term ; and the receiver of taxes, similarly chosen. Of these 
 officers, the comptroller is most important in directing the 
 financial policy of the city. He has general supervision over 
 
 1 See Annotated Charter of New York (second edition); E. Dana Du- 
 rand, The Finances of New York City. The Comptroller's Annual Report 
 contains a very detailed analysis of New York revenues.
 
 190 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the finances of the city, while the work of auditing is also 
 conducted in his department. More than any other officer, 
 he has the power to direct the fiscal policy of the city. 
 
 The principal items in the revenue of Philadelphia are, in 
 round numbers: 
 
 Taxes $18,415,000 
 
 Municipal industries 6,073,000 
 
 Licenses 2,103,000 
 
 Departmental receipts 1,127,000 
 
 State grants 910,000 
 
 Special assessments 710,000 
 
 Public-service privileges 113,000 
 
 Taxes are levied on real property, which amounts to $910,- 
 000,000, and $427,000,000 of personalty. On real property 
 three rates are levied: a "city rate" of $1.50, a "suburban 
 rate" of $1, and a "farm rate" of $0.75. The "farm rate" 
 applies to land used for agricultural purposes; the "suburban 
 rate," to property partially equipped with sewer and water 
 connections, and urban improvements; and the full rate, 
 to fully improved property. Practically all of the valuation 
 is based on the "city" property, however. On personal 
 property there is a rate of 40 cents per $100, of which one- 
 fourth goes to the state. Taxes are assessed in advance of 
 the fiscal year for which the levy is made. Thus the 1905 
 tax is assessed in 1904, the lists are revised, the tax levy made, 
 and the budget voted before the beginning of the fiscal year 
 1905. The tax is collected during the current fiscal year, 
 the bulk of it being paid in the month of August, as the penalty 
 begins September 1. Except for the 40 cents per $100 on 
 personal property, the state receives no general tax from 
 local property. An elaborate system of corporation taxes 
 and miscellaneous licenses obviates the necessity of any con- 
 siderable local taxation for state purposes. 
 
 A special form of tax' in Philadelphia is the mercantile 
 license tax. This is based on the whole volume of business 
 transacted annually by dealers in merchandise. Retailers 
 are required to pay a license fee of $1 per $1000 on the whole
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 191 
 
 volume of business transacted annually; wholesalers pay at 
 the rate of 50 cents per $1000; exchanges and boards of 
 trade, at the rate of 25 cents per $1000. Returns are made 
 by dealers to a board of mercantile appraisers appointed 
 by the state auditor and the city treasurer. Dealers may 
 be required to appear in person, and to produce books and 
 papers necessary to show the amount of business transacted. 
 The returns made are not published, nor are they open to 
 public inspection. From this source about $190,000 is paid 
 to the state by retail merchants, and $160,000 by wholesale 
 dealers, a total of about $350,000. Under this system there 
 is of course no tax on the goods or wares of the dealers so 
 licensed. The city does not share in the returns from this 
 form of license. 1 
 
 From licenses Philadelphia derives a revenue of about 
 $2,000,000. The principal item in this amount is the saloon 
 license of $1,800,000. The rate is fixed at $1,103.75, of 
 which the state receives $100. The sum of $105,000 is ob- 
 tained from street-car licenses of $50 a car and $100 for cars 
 crossing a bridge. In 1904 there were 225 "bridge" cars, 
 and 1945 ordinary cars. 2 In addition to this, a number of 
 charges are made in the shape of paving requirements and 
 taxes on dividends. Other items of license revenue are com- 
 paratively small, but a considerable amount is paid directly 
 to the state for miscellaneous licenses, such as those required 
 of bottlers, brokers, auctioneers, etc. 3 
 
 The revenue from municipal industries in Philadelphia is 
 about $6,000,000. The most important of the items that 
 make up this total is the $3,500,000 paid by the water depart- 
 
 1 There is also a poll-tax in Philadelphia, from which about $25,000 
 is obtained annually. The law has required the payment of the poll-tax 
 as a qualification for suffrage. 
 
 2 See F. W. Speirs, "The Street Railway System of Philadelphia," 
 Johns Hopkins University Studies, 15th Series, Nos. Ill, IV, V (1897). 
 
 3 Philadelphia County paid to the state (1903) for bottlers, $110,000; 
 brewers, $83,000; wholesale liquor-dealers, $180,000; bankers, $16,000; 
 eating-houses, $20,000.
 
 192 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ment. Other important items are the rent of wharves and 
 landings, from which about $50,000 is realized, and the rent 
 of city real estate, amounting to about $16,000. Another 
 large sum is the amount obtained from interest on public 
 deposits. This reached a total of $281,491 in 1903. Interest 
 is paid at the rate of 2 per cent on daily deposits, which in 
 Philadelphia are very large. The average balance carried 
 by the city in the seventy-nine banks and trust companies 
 used as depositories is about $20,000,000. The law provides 
 that the deposits placed in any one institution shall not 
 exceed 25 per cent of its capital stock and surplus. A list 
 of depositaries, seventy-nine in number, with the balances 
 in each and the amount of interest paid by each, is printed 
 in the comptroller's annual report of 1903 (pp. 28 and 46). 
 Another very considerable source of revenue in Philadelphia 
 is the lease of the gas-works. The United Gas Improve- 
 ment Co. pays into the city treasury 10 per cent on all 
 collections for the sale of gas. This amounted, in 1903, to 
 $636,000,* and has doubled within the last four years. 
 
 Receipts from the various city departments amount to 
 $1,127,000. A great part of this comes from the county 
 officers : for example, the recorder of deeds pays in $145,000 ; 
 the registrar of wills, $106,000; the sheriff, $50,000; the 
 prothonotary, $60,000. Institutions for the insane pay 
 $125,000; building inspection, $45,000; boiler inspection, 
 $26,000. 
 
 State grants in Philadelphia are placed at $910,000. Of 
 this practically all is designed for school purposes, as is the 
 case in other cities where such grants are made. This amount 
 is apportioned on the basis of the "exact number of taxable 
 citizens" in the respective school districts of the state. 2 
 
 Special assessments in Philadelphia amount to only $700,- 
 
 1 1898, $193,000; 1899, $340,000; 1900, $375,000; 1901, $416,000; 
 1902, $476,000. 
 
 1 There is also a state tax of 2 per cent on gross premiums of foreign 
 fire insurance companies, of which one-half is paid to the several cities 
 and boroughs as a fund for disabled firemen.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 193 
 
 000, as compared with $4,000,000 for Chicago and $7,000,000 
 for New York. This is due to the fact that a large amount 
 of repaying and repairing of streets is done by the city itself. 
 In 1904 the appropriation for the bureau of highways was 
 $3,270,000, of which practically all was applied to repairs 
 of streets. The returns from what would elsewhere be termed 
 special assessments appear as charges under various depart- 
 ments. Under the bureau of surveys a charge is made for 
 paving, sewers, curbing, etc. These charges are assessed 
 by the surveyor, and are collected by the contractor instead 
 of by the city. 
 
 Public-service privileges, as reported by the Census Bulletin 
 ($113,000), are smaller in Philadelphia than in any city of 
 its size. This sum is made up by the payments made to 
 the city on the part of the street railways. The rate is fixed 
 at 6 per cent of all dividends paid by the company above 
 6 per cent, or in some cases at 6 per cent on all dividends, 
 according to the terms of the various charters. In addition 
 to this payment and to the car license already noted, there 
 are considerable contributions made by the street railway 
 companies for the purpose of paving and repairing streets. 
 All but one of the companies are obliged to keep in repair and 
 good order all streets occupied by their tracks. Further- 
 more, there is a general state tax of one-half of 1 per cent on 
 capital stock, and of eight-tenths of 1 per cent on gross re- 
 ceipts. In 1897 Mr. Speirs estimated these various contribu- 
 tions as follows: 
 
 Paving and repairing $450,000 
 
 Dividends 92,000 
 
 Car license 97,000 
 
 Total $639,000 
 
 Tax on capital stock $432,844 
 
 Tax on gross receipts 91,391 
 
 ' Grand total $1,163,235 
 
 This does not include taxes on real estate or interest on invest- 
 ment in pavements. Under this heading might be included
 
 194 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the large payments made by the gas company to the city, 
 but this has been already discussed in the consideration of 
 municipal industries. 
 
 The collection of these items of revenue is centralized in 
 the receiver of taxes. Practically all moneys are paid in 
 to him, including taxes, real and personal, and water rents. 
 The payment by the gas company is made to the treasurer, 
 and also the saloon licenses. Court fees are paid to the vari- 
 ous court officers and later deposited with the treasurer. 
 
 The auditing of accounts is conducted in the office of the 
 comptroller, under the direction of the chief auditor. In 
 the examination and verification of revenues alone there are 
 twenty men employed, and another twenty are engaged in 
 the work of auditing the expenditures. Of those occupied 
 on the revenues, seven work on taxes, four on water collec- 
 tions, three on gas company payments, and five are classed 
 as miscellaneous. This makes possible a careful examina- 
 tion of the various sources of city income, with a view to 
 determining whether all accounts due are collected and 
 turned into the treasury, and the stopping-up of any leaks 
 in the sources of supply. 
 
 The debt of Philadelphia amounts to $58,000,000, or, sub- 
 tracting the sinking-fund assets, $50,654,640. This gives 
 a burden of debt per capita of $36.86. As an offset to this 
 there are, however, assets of importance to be taken into con- 
 sideration. These assets reach a total of $200,000,000, in- 
 cluding such items as waterworks ($59,000,000), gas-works 
 ($27,000,000), City Hall ($27,000,000), parks (about $30,000,- 
 000), and public trust funds ($21,000,000). In the presence 
 of such assets as these, the debt of the city appears to be 
 inconsiderable. 
 
 Among the important features of the Pennsylvania system 
 are the practical elimination of the general property tax as 
 a source of state revenue. The only state rate now levied 
 is the 40 cents on personal property, of which only one-fourth 
 is retained by the state. The state, in return for this, levies
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 195 
 
 extensive corporation taxes, which fall heavily on Phila- 
 delphia, and receives further support from the mercantile- 
 license system and from other miscellaneous licenses. An- 
 other important feature is the method of assessment of taxes 
 in advance of the fiscal year, thus making possible the col- 
 lection of taxes during the current fiscal year. Another 
 interesting aspect of the Philadelphia situation is the small 
 revenue realized from special assessments. Finally, the con- 
 solidation of city and county, with the accompanying unity 
 of financial administration, ought not to be ignored. This 
 concentration of power makes possible a centralized control 
 of all receipts and disbursements, locating power and respon- 
 sibility at a point that is not only ascertainable, but eminent 
 and conspicuous. 1 
 
 ST. LOUIS 
 
 The corporate authorities of St. Louis have jurisdiction 
 over practically the entire field of local revenues and expen- 
 ditures. The county proper of St. Louis covers only the terri- 
 tory lying outside of the city. The school board, an elective 
 body of twelve members, is, however, an independent finan- 
 cial agent, and the public library board is separated from 
 the city financially. The principal financial authorities of 
 the city a comptroller, an auditor, a treasurer, a collector, 
 and a president of the board of assessors are elected by 
 the people for a term of four years. The mayor, the comp- 
 troller, and the treasurer also constitute a fund commission. 
 
 Of these officers, the chief is the comptroller, who is most 
 active in the direction of the fiscal policy of the city. He 
 has general supervision of the finances of the city, and is 
 entitled to a seat in either branch of the municipal assembly, 
 and to the right to speak, but not to vote. The auditor is 
 practically the chief accountant, and the treasurer has merely 
 the custody of the city funds. 
 
 1 See a Digest of Laws and Ordinances Concerning Philadelphia, 1905.
 
 196 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The principal items in the revenue of St. Louis are as 
 follows : 
 
 Taxes $9,456,773 
 
 Licenses 1,669,946 
 
 State grants 202,251 
 
 Municipal industries 2,173,037 
 
 Public-service privileges 266,439 
 
 Departmental receipts 518,622 
 
 Special assessments 3,261,143 
 
 Total, including miscellaneous $17,608,112 
 
 The principal item in the revenues of St. Louis, as in the 
 other cities considered, is the general property tax, while 
 special features of this system are the parts played by the 
 state board of equalization and the merchants' and manu- 
 facturers' license and tax. The local assessment is in the 
 hands of the president of the board of assessors, an elective 
 officer, and deputy assessors appointed by the mayor. As 
 in Philadelphia, the system of assessment in advance is em- 
 ployed. Thus assessment for 1905 taxes was begun June 1, 
 1904, and completed by the next January. The assessments 
 are then passed upon by the board of equalization, consisting 
 of the president of the board of assessors and four appointees 
 of the circuit court, who must complete their work by the 
 fourth Monday in May. In addition to this local assessment, 
 the state board of equalization assesses railway property, 
 including street railways, and returns the amounts to the 
 city on the basis of main line mileage. 
 
 Collections are made by the city collector, the bulk of the 
 tax coming in during the first week of September and the 
 last week in December. A rebate at the rate of 8 per cent 
 from the date of payment to December 31 following is made 
 on all bills paid before October 1. School and library taxes 
 are collected by the city in the general collection. 
 
 The assessed valuation of St. Louis for 1903^ was : 
 
 Real estate $337,592,210 
 
 Personal 78,232,310 
 
 By state board 28,041,042 
 
 Total $443,865,562
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 
 
 197 
 
 On this the rate of taxation was 2.19, distributed in this 
 way: 
 
 
 
 CHICAGO BASIS 
 
 State 
 
 0.17 
 
 0.85 
 
 Public schools 
 City 
 
 0.55 
 1.43 
 
 2.75 
 7.15 
 
 Public library 
 
 0.04 
 
 0.20 
 
 
 2.19 
 
 10.95 
 
 A striking feature of the St. Louis system is the merchants' 
 and manufacturers' special tax and license. The law speci- 
 fies that : 
 
 Each merchant, mercantile firm, or corporation is required to fur- 
 nish the License Collector a statement of the value of the largest 
 amount of all goods, wares, and merchandise which he may have 
 had in his possession or under his control at any time, between the 
 first Monday of March and the first Monday of June in each year. 
 
 Each and every person defined to be a manufacturer shall furnish 
 to the License Collector a statement of the value of the greatest aggre- 
 gate amount of raw materials, merchandise, and finished products 
 (to be listed separately) which he had on hand on any one day be- 
 tween the first Monday of March and the first Monday of June in each 
 year, as well as all tools, machinery, and appliances used in conducting 
 his business or owned by him, on the first day of June in each year. 
 
 Each merchant or manufacturer shall furnish a statement of the 
 aggregate amount of all sales made during the year next preceding 
 the first Monday of June, of the then current year, verified by the 
 affidavit of the merchant, manufacturer, or officer of the corporation 
 making it. 
 
 On the merchandise and manufacturers' material a tax 
 of 92 cents per $100 is levied (regular tax-rate 2.19), while 
 on the gross sales a city license of $1 per $1000 is required. 
 Thus a merchant having a stock of the value of $10,000 and 
 sales of $50,000 will pay on the stock a tax of 92 cents, or 
 $92, and on sales a license fee of $1 per $1000, or $50; a 
 total of $142, tax and license. Sworn returns of stock and 
 sales are made to the collector, who has the right to examine 
 the books in order to test the accuracy of the returns. The
 
 198 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 lists are not published, but are open to inspection by the 
 public. $564,000 was realized from this source in 1904. 
 
 Licenses in St. Louis aggregate about $1,700,000 ($1,669,- 
 946). With the exception of the saloon licenses, they are 
 collected by the license commissioner, an officer appointed 
 by the mayor. The commissioner employs on the collection 
 of these miscellaneous revenues alone a force of twenty- 
 eight men, fourteen of whom operate in the field. The saloon 
 license in St. Louis is $600 a year, and $100 of this amount 
 goes to the state. Payments are made semiannually. About 
 $1,300,000 ($1,264,975.68) was realized from this source 
 during the year 1904. 
 
 Other important sources of income from licenses are : 
 
 Vehicles $74,831.50 
 
 Peddlers 26,596.70 
 
 Insurance companies, commission merchants, 
 
 restaurants, dogs, aggregate each about . 18,000.00 
 
 Hotels are taxed from $2.50 up; restaurants, $10 to $100; 
 intelligence offices, $300; banks, $100 each. 
 
 From municipal industries the city derives a revenue of 
 about $2,000,000 ($2,173,037). Water rates contribute almost 
 all of this amount, but there are minor receipts from wharf- 
 age and wharf rents, markets, and institutional industries. 
 
 The deposit of public funds with banks is in charge of the 
 mayor, comptroller, and treasurer, who select a bank or 
 banks offering the highest rate of interest. A deposit of 
 $500,000 is permitted in a single bank, with a possibility 
 of a supplementary deposit of $500,000 additional. There 
 are now ten depositaries, and interest is paid at the rate of 
 2.30 and 2.23 on daily balances. About $230,000, including 
 $25,000 interest on school funds, is realized from this source. 
 The average deposit on hand is about $7,000,000. 
 
 These revenues, with the exception of certain school funds, 
 are collected by the city. The greater part of the work is per- 
 formed by the city collector, but licenses are collected by the 
 license commissioner, water rates by the water department,
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 199 
 
 and some other items are collected by miscellaneous authori- 
 ties. Deposits are made daily with the city treasurer, with 
 some exceptions, notably the court fees. 
 
 Receipts from public-service privileges in St. Louis were, 
 in 1903, $266,439. The street-railway companies pay to 
 the city from 2^ to 5 per cent of their gross earnings, and 
 the amount reaches about $125,000. Telephone franchises, 
 on the same basis, bring in about $75,000; and from electric 
 companies about the same amount is paid in. Street cars 
 are licensed at the rate of $25 a year. In accordance with 
 the law of 1901, a franchise tax is levied on all special-privilege 
 corporations; but, except in the case of the gas company, 
 not much is obtained in this way, owing to the fact that local 
 charges are deducted from the amount of the franchise tax. 
 
 Departmental receipts amount to $518,622. Under this 
 are included such items as building permits ($20,792), boiler 
 and elevator inspection ($17,723), and fees of the various 
 court offices, of which latter $58,000 is returned for the record- 
 ing of deeds, and about $50,000 from the courts of record. 
 
 From special assessments $3,261,143 was collected in 1903. 
 They originate with the board of public improvements, and 
 must be approved by the municipal assembly. Taxes are 
 spread in proportion to area and frontage, one-fourth of the 
 cost being assessed on the frontage basis and three-fourths 
 on the area. The special assessments are not collected by 
 the city, but by the contractors themselves. 1 
 
 Among the important and suggestive features of the St. 
 Louis revenue system are the plan of advance assessment, 
 the special-privilege franchise tax, the merchants' and manu- 
 facturers' tax and license, and the general tendency toward 
 the universal business or "privilege tax." 2 
 
 1 In St. Louis special districts for street sprinkling are created and 
 specially taxed. The sum of $178,018.27 was thus collected in 1904-5. 
 2 See The Charter of the City of St. Louis; the Revised Ordinances; 
 Frederick N. Judson, Taxation in Missouri: Comptroller's Report, 
 1904-5; Report of the Board of Education ; Report of the Missouri 
 Tax Commission of 1903.
 
 200 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 BOSTON 
 
 The local government of Boston differs from that in New 
 York, Philadelphia, and St. Louis in having a number of 
 local authorities instead of a consolidated municipal govern- 
 ment. Moreover, the various authorities differ markedly 
 from those in Chicago; and the nearest analogy to the exist- 
 ing arrangements are those which existed for London before 
 the establishment of the county council. 
 
 In one important respect consolidation of authorities has 
 gone farther than in Chicago. Although Suffolk County com- 
 prises a small city and two smaller towns in addition to the 
 city of Boston, there are no separate county financial au- 
 thorities, and the county budget is included in the financial 
 statements for the city. But there are a number of special 
 boards outside of the city government charged with impor- 
 tant branches of local administration. Two of these the 
 police board and the rapid transit commission exercise 
 jurisdiction only within the city; and their accounts are 
 reported in the city financial statements. Two others, how- 
 ever, deal with a large territory outside of the city, known 
 as the metropolitan district. These are the metropolitan 
 sewer and water board, and the metropolitan park com- 
 mission, whose members are appointed by the governor and 
 council of Massachusetts, and derive their authority directly 
 from the state legislature. 
 
 This metropolitan district which differs slightly for 
 each of the two boards includes Boston and more than 
 a dozen cities and towns in the immediate neighborhood, 
 which are largely suburban regions of the one urban com- 
 munity. But for local sentiment and administrative diffi- 
 culties, the whole district might be included within the city 
 of Boston, which would then have a population of 1,100,000. 
 
 One result of the continuance of separate governments is 
 to make per capita statements of Boston finances a good 
 deal larger than if the whole metropolitan community were
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 201 
 
 included, as the heavy expenses within the business district 
 are distributed only over the population within the city 
 limits. Thus the total ordinary receipts for the city of Boston 
 for 1903 were $40.47 per capita. But if the receipts for the 
 eight other larger cities in the metropolitan district are added, 
 the aggregate is $32.84 per capita. If the smaller cities and 
 towns were included, the rate would be somewhat lower than 
 this. But the results would still leave the per capita receipts 
 and expenditures for Boston larger than for any other city. 
 
 For the most accurate analysis and comparison with other 
 cities, the finances of all of the cities and towns in the metro- 
 politan district should be combined. But the data for the 
 smaller places are not available; and it has seemed inad- 
 visable to present figures which were neither for the city of 
 Boston nor for the entire metropolitan district. Thus the 
 statements given in the tables are those for the city of Boston, 
 with its proportion of the transactions of the metropolitan 
 boards. 
 
 Boston's share of the ordinary revenues and expenditures 
 of the metropolitan boards is practically included in the 
 accounts of the city. The ordinary revenues of these boards 
 are received from assessments levied on the different cities 
 and towns; and the amounts show in Boston's reports as 
 included in the tax revenue, and as paid out to the metro- 
 politan boards. The census bulletin, however, includes all 
 of these payments under miscellaneous general expenses; 
 whereas they should be distributed as maintenance charges 
 for the different purposes, and as interest and sinking-fund 
 payments. This change has accordingly been made from 
 the census arrangement in the tabular statements. 
 
 On the other hand, the debt statements of the city of 
 Boston do not show its share of the debt incurred for the 
 metropolitan undertakings. The latter is nominally a state 
 debt; but in fact it will be paid only by the communities 
 within the metropolitan district. Accordingly, Boston's pro- 
 portion of this debt has been calculated on the basis of its
 
 202 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 share of the interest and sinking-fund payments; and this 
 has been included in the statement of debt in the tables. 
 
 As in the other American cities, the larger part of the city's 
 revenue is derived from the general property tax. This is 
 levied by an ordinance passing both branches of the city 
 council with the approval of the mayor. Department esti- 
 mates of proposed expenditure are compiled by the city 
 auditor and revised by the mayor; but the effective work 
 of determining the amount of the budget and the necessary 
 tax levy is done by the board of aldermen, the smaller branch 
 of the city council, which in this respect performs a similar 
 function to the board of estimate and apportionment in 
 New York City. The approval of the budget and tax levy 
 by the common council follows; and the ordinance is finally 
 subject to the veto power of the mayor. 
 
 While the per capita tax is high, it is important to note 
 that the tax-rate for Boston is lower than in most large 
 American cities. This is due to the high per capita valuation 
 of property, which is the result of several factors: the per 
 capita wealth of Boston is doubtless higher than in other 
 cities; the assessed valuation is close to the full market 
 value of property; and, as a consequence of the city includ- 
 ing only part of the residence districts, the high value of 
 business property is a larger proportion of all property within 
 the city limits. 
 
 In addition to the general property tax, a large revenue is 
 derived from special taxes, especially those on street railway, 
 bank, and other corporations. These taxes are levied by the 
 state, and are paid directly to the state by the corporations. 
 But the receipts are distributed to the cities and towns in 
 proportion to the number of shares of stock owned on the 
 miles of railroad track located in each. Thus, in effect, it is 
 a local tax collected by the state for the cities, and not a real 
 subvention from the state to the city. Grants from the 
 state government are, in fact, almost a negligible item in the 
 revenues of Boston.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 203 
 
 Revenue from licenses is mainly from the liquor traffic; 
 and the rates for liquor licenses rise higher than in any other 
 city. The minimum rate is $500, but this applies to only 
 a small number of places, while the greater number pay the 
 higher rates of $1100 and $2000. One-fourth of the revenue 
 from these licenses goes to the state; the remaining three- 
 fourths, to the city. As a result of the high license fee and 
 the restrictions on the granting of licenses, there were only 
 786 liquor saloons in Boston in 1903; yet the revenue to the 
 city was over $1,000,000. 
 
 Under receipts from public-service privileges are included 
 certain so-called taxes on public-service corporations. One 
 of these is a gross earnings "tax" on street railways, in lieu 
 of other payments for street repairs; the proceeds of the tax 
 being used for the repairs of streets. Another is a special 
 franchise "tax" on the elevated railway, specified to be in 
 consideration of special privileges granted. 
 
 Receipts of municipal industries are larger proportionately 
 in Boston than in other American cities. The waterworks 
 produced $2,349,726 in 1903, or 60 per cent of the water 
 revenue in Chicago, although the population of Boston is 
 less than a third of Chicago's. The municipal markets 
 brought in $110,000; and other industries, $480,000.' 
 
 TORONTO 
 
 For purposes of comparison with American cities, Toronto 
 has been selected. The general scheme of revenue-raising 
 corresponds roughly to our own, but differs in important 
 particulars. The revenue machinery of Toronto consists 
 of the treasurer and two auditors, appointed by the council 
 for an indefinite term, an assessment commissioner, also 
 appointed by the council, together with assessors, valuators, 
 and collectors, who are selected by the commissioner. There 
 is also a court of revision of assessments, composed of three 
 
 1 See Boston Municipal Register; Auditor's Report; Publications of 
 Bureau of Statistics.
 
 204 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 members, one appointed by the mayor, one by the council, 
 and the official arbitrator, and the two auditors. Practi- 
 cally financial authority is vested in the two officers, treasurer 
 and commissioner, subject to the direction and control of 
 the council. Although the term of office is indefinite, tenure 
 is practically permanent, as removals are rare. The present 
 city treasurer entered the service of the city in 1873, and has 
 occupied his present position since 1888. 
 
 The total revenue of Toronto for the year 1903 was about 
 $4,000,000. Of this by far the largest item was that of taxes, 
 which amounted to $3,133,219. Taxes are derived from a 
 levy of $1.90 per $100 on a valuation of about $138,000,000. 
 There is also an income tax, with exemptions on income from 
 personal earnings to the amount of $400 to $1000. Tele- 
 graph and telephone companies are especially taxed on 75 
 per cent of their gross receipts (in cities of over 100,000 
 inhabitants). 
 
 This year there goes into effect a law providing for what is 
 termed " business assessment " ; the essential feature of this sys- 
 tem is the use of the rental value of business property as an in- 
 dication of income or ability to pay. The law provides that 
 
 Irrespective of any assessment of land under this act, every person 
 occupying or using land in the municipality for the purpose of any 
 business mentioned or described in this section shall be assessed for a 
 sum to be called " business assessment," to be computed by reference 
 to the assessed value of the land so occupied or used by him, as 
 follows : 
 
 Every person carrying on the business of a distiller is 
 assessed for a sum equal to 150 per cent of the said assessed 
 value; brewers at 75 per cent; retail merchants at 25 per 
 cent; solicitors, physicians, etc., at 50 per cent; telegraph, 
 telephone, street-railway companies at 15 per cent. In case 
 the income of an individual so assessed exceeds the assess- 
 ment, he is liable on the extent to which such income exceeds 
 the amount of business assessment. 
 
 Among the interesting features of the taxing system is the
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 205 
 
 system of rotation in assessment. The work of valuation 
 is begun in March, and carried on ward by ward until the city 
 is covered, in September. A distinction is made, in assess- 
 ment, between improved and unimproved property, and there 
 is now on foot a movement to exempt improvements up to 
 the value of $700. It is also important to observe that the 
 Toronto assessment is made in advance of the year for which 
 the levy is made. This makes possible the collection of taxes 
 during the current fiscal year as in Philadelphia and St. 
 Louis, and obviates' the necessity for borrowing largely in 
 anticipation of incoming taxes. 
 
 Liquor licenses amounted (in 1903) to about $32,000, at 
 a rate of $450. Of this the city receives approximately $166, 
 while the balance goes to the Province of Ontario. The 
 administration of this license is in the fact superintended by 
 provincial officers, independently of the city. The number 
 of licenses is fixed at one hundred and fifty hotels and fifty 
 shops, and the policy is to reduce rather than to increase the 
 number. From other licenses about $37,000 is obtained, 
 with the sums obtained on account of milk venders, peddlers, 
 expressmen, and cigarettes, yielding largest returns. 
 
 The principal municipal industry is the waterworks, 
 which pays about $400,000 a year. Rentals of city property 
 bring in about $170,000 (including certain rentals charged 
 against police stations and other departments); about 
 $25,000 is obtained from the city markets. The Industrial 
 Exposition in 1903 netted some $31,000. 
 
 In public-service privileges the leading item is the revenue 
 obtained from the street-railway companies. In return for 
 a thirty-year franchise the city receives a percentage of the 
 gross receipts on the following scale: 
 
 Up to $1,000,000 8% 
 
 From $1,000,000 to $1,500,000 10% 
 
 From $1,500,000 to $2,000,000 12% 
 
 From $2,000,000 to $3,000,000 15% 
 
 Above $3,000,000 20%
 
 206 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 In addition to this, the city receives compensation in the 
 shape of mileage at the rate of $800 per single-track mile. 
 The amount realized from street railways was, in 1903, 
 $279,000. In 1904 this was increased to $323,000, and is 
 estimated for 1905 at $345,000. 
 
 Special assessments are levied for the ordinary purposes, 
 but in Toronto such taxes may also be made for the purpose 
 of sweeping, lighting, and watering streets, for cutting grass 
 and weeds, and for removal of snow, ice, and dirt. A con- 
 siderable part of the cost of local improvements is borne by 
 the city. Thus, in 1903, the cost of such improvements 
 was about $665,000, of which $468,000 was paid by the prop- 
 erty owners, and the balance by the city. 
 
 The indebtedness of the city is about $21,500,000, from 
 which deduction must be made for cash and sinking-fund. 
 This leaves a net debt (December 31, 1903) of $15,316,266. 
 Estimating the population at 200,000 in 1903, the per capita 
 debt is about $75. Of this debt about five and one-half 
 millions have been incurred for the purpose of local 
 improvements. 1 
 
 SECTION III. REVENUES OF FOREIGN CITIES 2 
 
 Revenue-raising Bodies in European Cities. Financial 
 study has been made of five of the principal large cities of 
 
 1 See Consolidated Municipal Act of 1903 ; Consolidated By-Laws of the 
 City of Toronto, 1904; City Treasurer's Annual Report ; Municipal Hand- 
 book of the City of Toronto; The Assessment Act (Ontario), 4 Edw. VII, 
 ch. 23 (1904). 
 
 2 BIBLIOGRAPHY. British Parliamentary Papers ; Annual Local Taxa- 
 tion Returns (England and Wales), 1902-1903; Annual Local Taxation 
 Returns (Scotland, 1901-1902); Annual Reports of the Accountant for Scot- 
 land to the Scotch Education Department, 1901-1902, 1902-1903; Revenue 
 and Expenditure (England, Scotland, and Ireland), 1902-1903; Atkin- 
 son, Local Government in Scotland, chs. 15-17; Oesterreichisches Stadte- 
 buch, Vol. X (1904); Die Gemeinde-Verwaltung der Stadt Wien fur das 
 Jahr 1902; Statistisches Jahrbuch der Stadt Wien fur das Jahr 1902; 
 Statistisches Jahrbuch der autonomen Landesverwaltung (1904); Oester- 
 reichisches Statistisches Handbuch (1903); Oesterreichische Statistik, Vol.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 207 
 
 Europe London, Paris, Berlin, Vienna, and Glasgow. In 
 order to present data covering the same objects of expenditure, 
 it has been necessary to combine, in most cases, the financial 
 accounts of several local authorities and certain items from 
 the accounts of the central governments ; and as the accounts 
 and reports of the various countries and cities are on very 
 different plans, this has required a careful rearrangement of 
 the items in the reports so as to group substantially similar 
 facts in a uniform schedule. 
 
 London shows the greatest multiplicity in the number of 
 authorities whose accounts must be considered, more than 
 Chicago. Moreover, no single local authority occupies even 
 the same degree of relative importance that the city corporate 
 has in Chicago. As various authorities have jurisdiction 
 over different areas and population, it is not obvious what 
 district to include; but the most suitable district is that 
 known as the administrative county of London, with a 
 population of 4,560,000. 
 
 Within this district the most important single authority 
 is the county council, a popularly elected body. This has 
 control over certain large municipal works, such as the main 
 drainage system, some of the leading thoroughfares, most of 
 the bridges over the river Thames, and the principal parks; 
 and also has charge of the fire brigade, owns and operates 
 street-railway lines, and exercises some specified powers of 
 police and sanitary control. 
 
 At the present time the London county council is also 
 
 LXX (" Der Oesterreichische Staatshaushalt in 1899 and 1900 ") Comptc 
 general des recettes et depenses de la mile de Paris, Exercice 1902; Departe- 
 ment de la Seine: Compte des recettes et des depenses, Exercice 1902; 
 Budget de la mile de Paris, Exercice 1903 (tableaux annexes) ; Annuaire 
 statistique de la ville de Paris (1901); Compte general de I' administration 
 des finances (Republique Frangaise, 1902); Annuaire statistique de la 
 France (1903). Statistisches Jahrbuch der Stadt Berlin, Vols. XXVII, 
 XXVIII; Verwaltungsbericht des Magistrats zu Berlin filr 1902; Ver- 
 waltungsbericht der Koniglichen Polizei-Prdsidium zu Berlin (1891-1900) ; 
 Statistisches Handbuch des Preussischen Stoat, Vol. IV ; R. C. Brooks in 
 Political Science Quarterly, XX, 665.
 
 208 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the local educational authority ; but for the years represented 
 in the financial statements there was a specially elected 
 school board, an independent corporation with its own 
 taxing powers. 
 
 Most of the administrative county and a large area beyond 
 is included in the metropolitan police district. The police 
 force and police courts are directly under the control of 
 a commissioner, appointed by the central government; 
 but a large part of the expenses of this force are collected 
 by local taxes or rates. For the purpose of this study only 
 that part of the police district within the administrative 
 county has been included. 
 
 Another metropolitan district created is that for the supply 
 of water, which also includes territory beyond the county. 
 This function is now under the control of a water board, 
 composed of representatives of the various locally elected 
 authorities within the district. But at the time represented 
 in this report the water supply for the metropolis was in the 
 hands of a number of private companies, and their accounts 
 are not included. 
 
 Another authority in the county of London is the metro- 
 politan asylums board, consisting mainly of representatives 
 from certain locally elected authorities, which has the manage- 
 ment of public hospitals, including those for the indigent sick 
 and those for infectious diseases. 
 
 Within the administrative county there are twenty-eight 
 metropolitan boroughs, the city of Westminster and the 
 city of London, each with its own elected council and other 
 officials. These control many municipal public works, such 
 as street-paving, lighting, and cleaning, garbage disposal, 
 and local sewers. Many of them have electric-light plants, 
 bath-houses, and public libraries, and some have small parks. 
 The city of London (whose -jurisdiction covers only a small 
 part of the county) has a larger range of functions than the 
 metropolitan boroughs, including a police force and several 
 bridges over the Thames.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 209 
 
 Also within the administrative county are thirty poor- 
 law unions, each with an elected board of poor-law guardians. 
 These, in connection with the metropolitan asylums board, 
 control the administration of poor-relief. 
 
 Finally there is the Thames conservancy board, which has 
 control over navigation and boat landings on the river 
 Thames; but this does not include the docks and ware- 
 houses for sea traffic, which are owned by private companies. 
 
 In addition to these various authorities, there must be 
 included certain expenses of the imperial government, which 
 correspond to items of local expense in Chicago and other 
 American cities. The entire cost of the judicial and penal 
 administration is borne by the central government; and 
 a number of the public parks and museums in London are 
 owned and maintained as royal parks. Some part of the 
 expense for these must be considered as an additional grant 
 from the central government to local purposes. The appor- 
 tionment to London of the total expense for these items has 
 had to be made approximately on a somewhat arbitrary basis. 
 
 In the case of the continental cities the number of local 
 authorities is less, and the task of forming a consolidated 
 statement is less difficult; but even for these there is usually 
 more than one local budget to be considered. For Paris 
 there are two main divisions in the administration of the city, 
 one under the prefect of the Seine and the other under the 
 prefect of the police. But the accounts of both of these are 
 presented in a single budget and financial report. To these 
 city accounts, however, there must be added a large share of 
 the financial transactions of the department of the Seine. 
 These are for the most part of a local character; and as Paris 
 has two-thirds of the population of the department, they 
 are in large measure part of the local administration assign- 
 able to the Paris community. 
 
 In addition to these local accounts, there must be included 
 some expenses of the national government, which are analo- 
 gous to local expenditure in this country. The national grant
 
 210 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 toward the support of the Paris police is included in the city 
 budget ; but other items in the national budget riot appearing 
 there are for the local share of judicial and penal administra- 
 tion, and for the support of various educational and art 
 institutions. These must be added to those in the local ac- 
 counts to make a fair comparison with other cities ; although 
 in some cases only an approximate estimate can be made of 
 the amount assignable to Paris. 
 
 In Berlin there is but one local corporation for municipal 
 purposes; and all of the strictly local expenditures are ac- 
 counted for on one budget. But again, as in Paris, the 
 central state government, besides contributing small grants 
 to the municipal treasury, carries on under its direct control 
 certain important services which in the United States are 
 branches of local administration; and the larger share of the 
 expenses for these comes from the state treasury, without 
 appearing in the municipal budget. These services include 
 the courts and correctional institutions, the police com- 
 mission (which controls the police force, fire department, 
 and health and inspection services), the public schools, and 
 the principal public parks. For any fair comparison of local 
 finances in Berlin and Chicago, it is therefore necessary to 
 include the expenses of these services in addition to the items 
 in the municipal accounts. The expenses of the Berlin police 
 commission are shown separately in the financial reports of 
 Prussia. But for the other services an apportionment of the 
 total expenditure for the whole country must be made; and 
 here a rough approximation of the amount chargeable to Berlin 
 is all that can be given. 
 
 For Vienna the local accounts to be considered are those of 
 the city corporation and those of the province of Lower 
 Austria. The latter, as in the case of the department of the 
 Seine and Paris, carries on functions which are for the most 
 part local in character; and as Vienna has more than half 
 the population of the province, a large share of the items in 
 the provincial accounts are assignable to the city.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 211 
 
 So, too, as for the other European cities, there must be 
 taken from the Austrian central government accounts some 
 items for branches of administration undertaken in the 
 United States by the local authorities. This is less important 
 in Vienna than in Paris or Berlin, but some part of the ex- 
 penses for courts and prisons, and for the royal parks, in 
 Vienna are clearly for the benefit of the city community, and 
 this can be at least roughly apportioned. 
 
 To make up the Glasgow statistics has required the con- 
 solidation of the reports of a large number of local authorities, 
 though not so many as in London. If the areas of juris- 
 diction of different authorities were coterminous, it would 
 be necessary to include only the accounts of the city, the 
 parish, and the school board of Glasgow. But as the parish 
 boundaries overlap those of the city, it has been found most 
 convenient to include the data for the city of Glasgow and 
 three small adjacent boroughs, and also those of two parishes 
 and four school boards, covering the same area and population. 
 This district, with a population of 912,000, is all within the 
 Glasgow urban community. 
 
 Comparison of Sources of Revenue. From the revenue 
 statement it appears that the total ordinary revenue per 
 capita for each of these European cities considered is larger 
 than that for Chicago. But this is in part a result of the larger 
 gross revenue from municipal industries, especially in Berlin 
 and Glasgow; and this income is largely offset by the special 
 expenses of these undertakings. For general revenue, which 
 is a better basis of comparison, the per capita for Chicago is 
 also less than that for London or Paris; but larger than for 
 the other three cities. This, however, does not take into 
 consideration the relatively higher purchasing power of money 
 in Europe. 
 
 Except in Glasgow, the most important source of revenue 
 is that from taxation. This yields the great bulk of the 
 general revenue, and from 35 to 70 per cent of the total ordi- 
 nary revenue. The amount of taxes per capita is, like the
 
 212 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 general revenue, higher in money for London and Paris than 
 for Chicago; and while less in Berlin, Vienna, and Glasgow, 
 the difference is probably smaller than the difference in the 
 value of property, or in the purchasing power of money. 
 The methods of taxation are, however, very different from 
 those in America, and also show great variety between the 
 various foreign cities. And a brief analysis of the taxing 
 systems will be suggestive in considering changes in methods 
 here. 
 
 London and Glasgow have systems of direct local taxes 
 which are very similar to each other; but this British system 
 is very different from that used in other countries. The 
 direct local taxes are wholly independent and distinct from 
 the taxes levied by or for the central government, and the 
 differentiation is so marked that the term "taxes" is not 
 applied to the local contributions, which are known as "rates" 
 in England and " assessments " in Scotland. These local rates 
 and assessments are levied on real estate only, including land 
 and buildings : and the basis of the levy in both countries is, 
 not the capital value of the property, but the annual rental 
 value. Moreover, the local rates are levied largely on the 
 tenants or occupiers, instead of only on the owners, of property. 
 In London, however (and generally in England), it is very 
 often arranged in the leases that the landlord shall pay the 
 occupiers' rates, and the rents are arranged accordingly. 
 This is known as "compounding" the rates. In Glasgow and 
 Scotland there is little or no compounding ; but a considerable 
 portion of the assessments are levied directly against the 
 owners. 
 
 While there is only one system of valuation and assess- 
 ment, there are a great number of distinct rates levied for 
 different purposes. Almost every one of the many local 
 authorities levies a separate 'rate, and in some cases one au- 
 thority levies several rates. Thus there are separate rates for 
 poor-relief, schools, borough purposes, and sanitary improve- 
 ments; while in London there is an additional county rate.
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 213 
 
 A somewhat complicated process is followed in making 
 valuations. There is first determined the "gross estimated 
 rental," based on the yearly rent paid by a tenant who him- 
 self pays the tithes and the occupiers' rates. From this de- 
 ductions are made to cover the average expenses for repairs, 
 insurance, and renewals, and the balance is the "ratable 
 value." In Glasgow, however, the burgh rates are levied on 
 the gross rental. For certain purposes and certain kinds of 
 property rates are levied only on a fraction of the full ratable 
 value. Rates for police and street-lighting are levied on 
 lands only on one-third of the full value; and rates for sani- 
 tary and other municipal improvements are based only on 
 one-fourth of the value for agricultural land, railroads, docks, 
 and canals. On the other hand, the assessment is always 
 based on the value of the property for the purpose in use, 
 so that the "franchise value" of railways, gas-works, and the 
 like are included. 
 
 In London the primary valuations are made by the coun- 
 cils of the metropolitan boroughs, subject to review by assess- 
 ment committees and appeal to the courts. There are some 
 provisions for establishing uniform methods throughout the 
 metropolis. Complete revaluations are required by statute 
 every five years, and the deductions from the gross rentals 
 are based on a fixed scale. There are also provisions for 
 equalizing certain rates between the poorer and richer dis- 
 tricts. 
 
 In the continental cities most of the direct taxes, and some- 
 times part of the indirect taxes, levied by the local authorities, 
 are in the form of additions to the taxes levied by the central 
 governments. This resembles the method in America of 
 adding the local tax rate to the rate levied by the state govern- 
 ments ; but in the European cities the taxes for the central 
 governments are the larger portion of the whole, although 
 the local taxes are also of weight. It is important to keep 
 this condition in mind when comparing the total burden of 
 taxation in American and European cities. In Chicago the
 
 214 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 state tax does not amount to one-tenth the local tax, and in 
 other cities the proportion is equally small. 
 
 In Paris the direct local taxes are known as centimes addi- 
 tionels, because the rate is measured in centimes added to the 
 rate for state taxes. There are four separate objects of this 
 direct taxation lands and buildings, personal property, 
 doors and windows, and business trades. 
 
 Indirect taxes still form a slightly larger source of local 
 revenue in Paris than the direct taxes, and are of much more 
 importance in Paris than in other French cities. These in- 
 direct taxes, known as octrois, are an elaborate series of 
 local customs duties levied on goods entering the city. The 
 larger part of the revenue comes from the duties on wines, 
 beers, and other liquors; meat and other food supplies 
 are also taxed, but bread is admitted free. The adminis- 
 tration of these octrois duties at the city gates and rail- 
 road stations is very expensive, the total cost amounting 
 to over 10 per cent of the amount collected. There is 
 much complaint about them; but the heavy direct taxes 
 by the state stand in the way of increasing these so as to 
 abolish the octrois. 
 
 In Berlin most of the local taxes, and nearly all of the tax 
 revenue, may be classed as direct. The most significant 
 feature is the tax on incomes, levied by the municipality in 
 addition to the state income tax. Although the Prussian 
 government ten years ago abandoned other direct taxes for 
 state revenue, with a view to segregating the state and local 
 sources of revenue, the municipal income tax still furnishes 
 nearly half of the municipal tax income or about 40 per 
 cent, if the special assessments are included as direct taxes. 
 Next in importance is the tax on real estate, which yields 
 about two-thirds as much as the municipal income tax. 
 This has been levied on the basis of rentals, as in England; 
 but a change to the system of capital market value has recently 
 been adopted, so as to reach the owners of unimproved land. 
 About 15 per cent of the tax revenue comes from business
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 215 
 
 or trade taxes, which include a small amount from depart- 
 ment stores, and still less ($75,000) from retail liquor dealers. 
 Of minor importance are the taxes on real-estate transfers, 
 brewers, and dogs, which may be considered as indirect taxes. 
 The revenue from these all together is less than 5 per cent of 
 the total tax revenue. 
 
 Vienna also secures a large part of its tax revenue from 
 additions to the taxes of the central government. But the 
 taxes in force are different from those in Prussia or France. 
 The land tax is insignificant, and the most important direct 
 state taxes used for local revenues are the tax on buildings 
 and the inheritance taxes. In addition to these, the city 
 gets a large revenue (as much as from the other direct taxes 
 combined) from a tax on rents, apparently similar to the 
 British local taxes. Vienna also, like Paris, makes a large 
 use of indirect taxes, which are levied mostly on liquors and 
 meats. A good share of this revenue comes as an addition 
 to the state excises on the same commodities; but some dis- 
 tinctly local consumption taxes are also levied. 
 
 A considerable part of the funds for municipal purposes 
 in the European cities comes from the central governments. 
 Part of this is in the form of grants or subventions paid into 
 the treasury of the local authorities, part is in the form of 
 direct support of institutions which in this country are often 
 local in character. In Great Britain most of the amounts 
 shown are payments to local authorities, and the largest part 
 of these are the proceeds of certain local taxation licenses, 
 inheritance taxes, and probate duties levied and collected 
 by the central government, but paid over in whole or in part 
 to the local authorities. The most important of these are 
 excise duties on liquors and certain inheritance taxes. The 
 proceeds from these taxes are fixed in amount, and do not 
 increase from year to year. There are also, however, some 
 grants from other funds in the national treasury to local 
 authorities, mostly for schools; while some expenses for 
 national courts, prisons, parks, and museums, analogous to
 
 216 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 American local expenditure, have also been included as equiv- 
 alent to additional grants from the central government. 
 
 In the continental countries most of the revenue for local 
 purposes from the central governments are expended under 
 its immediate control. The largest amounts are for the police 
 of the various cities; but other items partly assignable to 
 the localities are those for courts, prisons, secondary schools, 
 art and other museums, and parks. There are also some 
 grants or subventions to the local treasuries for elementary 
 schools, and occasionally in small amounts for other pur- 
 poses. 
 
 Revenue from public-service franchises are most striking 
 in the case of Paris. This is due to the small extent of mu- 
 nicipal ownership there, as compared with Berlin, Vienna, 
 and Glasgow. The gas company alone pays the city of 
 Paris over $3,000,000 a year. 
 
 Municipal-service income for the continental cities includes 
 some revenue more or less analogous to special assessments 
 in the United States. But the different methods employed 
 and the different purposes make it impossible to separate 
 exactly the amounts corresponding to special assessments. 
 Most of the revenue included under special assessments for 
 Berlin is from a rental tax for the maintenance of sewage 
 works. 
 
 Revenue from municipal property and industries varies 
 necessarily with the extent of municipalization. In propor- 
 tion to population, Glasgow stands first, Berlin and Vienna 
 second, with Paris and London farther behind. Glasgow 
 has municipal tramways, gas-works, electric lighting, water- 
 works, markets, and telephones; and more than half of the 
 total revenue is derived from these sources. Vienna owns all 
 of these industries, except telephones, but has not operated 
 the street railways. It also has municipal abattoirs and 
 cemeteries. Berlin has municipal water- and gas-works, 
 markets, and abattoirs. Paris has only municipal water- 
 works, markets, abattoirs, and cemeteries. London has,
 
 REVENUE SYSTEMS 217 
 
 in part, municipal electric lighting, cemeteries, markets, and 
 street railways; while the waterworks have come under 
 public control since the year covered by this report. 
 
 The revenue from these municipal industries is, for the most 
 part, offset by the special expenses; but in most of these 
 cities there seems to be an appreciable net revenue, which 
 balances the smaller receipts from public privileges in the 
 other cities as compared with Paris. 
 
 The extraordinary revenues necessary vary largely from 
 year to year. For the period covered in the tables Vienna 
 made a large loan of $28,000,000, mainly for the purchase of 
 the street-railway system; and London borrowed large 
 amounts for street improvements. 
 
 Comparison of Expenditures. From the statement of 
 expenditures it is seen, not only that the total ordinary ex- 
 penses of these European cities are larger per capita than 
 those of all the public authorities in Chicago, but also that, 
 except in the case of Glasgow, the total general expenses 
 (deducting the expenses of municipal industries) are larger 
 per capita than for Chicago. When, besides the actual differ- 
 ence in money spent, there is considered the higher rates of 
 wages, salaries, and prices generally in this country, it be- 
 comes evident that Chicago cannot expect to attain the stand- 
 ard of municipal service furnished by the European cities 
 without a substantial increase in the expenditure for munici- 
 pal purposes. 
 
 Examining the various items of expenditure, there are 
 seen to be wide variation in some lines between the different 
 European cities; and in some branches Chicago spends more 
 proportionately; notably for the fire department and public 
 parks. On the other hand, for certain objects the expendi- 
 ture of Chicago is unusually low. In the case of public 
 charities, this is probably due to the smaller need for assistance 
 in this country. But, in view of the inadequate protection 
 afforded by the police force in Chicago, it is significant to 
 note the much larger expenditure in London, Paris, and
 
 218 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Berlin. So, too, the expenditure for maintenance and care 
 of streets and sewers is markedly more in most of these cities 
 than in Chicago. The apparent exception in the case of 
 street-lighting expenditure for Berlin and Vienna is due to 
 the fact that the municipal lighting plants in these cities do 
 not keep an account for public lighting, as is the case in Glas- 
 gow. And while the expenditure for street and sewer con- 
 struction in Chicago seems large, most of this is on the 
 drainage canal, and the outlay for street-paving work is 
 comparatively small. 
 
 The expenses for courts assigned to Berlin and Vienna is 
 much higher than for the other European or the American 
 cities. But there is also a large revenue received by the 
 courts in Berlin and Vienna, which meets a large share of the 
 expense. It seems probable that the public accounts in 
 connection with the German and Austrian courts include 
 many items which in Great Britain, France, and the United 
 States are often settled privately with no public record. For 
 example, the financial reports of American courts show no 
 record of fees paid to referees or masters in chancery, or of 
 trust funds held by the court officials ; while it is likely that, 
 with more exact methods of accounting in Germany and 
 Austria, the corresponding financial transactions are included 
 in the official books of account.
 
 XI 
 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 1 
 
 THE Detroit municipal electric lighting plant was inaugu- 
 rated in 1895 and has now been in operation for more than 
 a decade. Except Chicago, it is the largest municipal plant 
 in this country ; and the results of ten years' experience under 
 a municipal system as compared with the previous system 
 of contract lighting should be of wide interest and value. 
 
 A brief historical sketch of electric lighting in Detroit under 
 both private and municipal management will serve to intro- 
 duce the discussion on the comparative results of the two 
 systems. Electric lighting was first introduced in Detroit in 
 1882; the following year an experimental contract was made 
 by the city for lighting two of the principal streets; and in 
 1884 the contract for the entire public lighting of the city 
 was awarded to the electric light company. Three hundred 
 arc lamps of 2000 candle power each were employed; but 
 in place of single lamps at frequent intervals, these were 
 grouped in seventy-two towers from 100 to 250 feet in height. 
 For these the city paid at the rate of $240 for each arc lamp. 
 Yearly contracts were made with the same company for each 
 of the next five years, the number of arc lamps increasing 
 steadily to 719 in 1890, and the cost per lamp falling by 
 stages to $191 in the same year. In 1890 another company 
 underbid the first company, and a three years' contract was 
 made with the new concern at approximately $130 a lamp. 
 The number of lamps was increased at once to over one thou- 
 
 1 Revised from an article in Municipal Affairs, IV, 606 (September, 
 1900). Data brought down to 1905. 
 
 219
 
 220 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 sand, and by 1894 there were 1279 arc lamps in use in the 
 public streets. A large number of single lamps were now 
 used in addition to the tower groups. 
 
 In the spring of 1893 proposals for a new contract for public 
 lighting were invited. The only bid received was from the 
 company then lighting the city, which submitted a schedule 
 of rates varying from $155.73 per lamp for a one-year con- 
 tract, to $124.10 for a three-year contract, and $102.20 for 
 a ten-year contract. The project for a municipal lighting 
 plant was already under serious consideration; and on the 
 recommendation of the comptroller, the proposal was rejected 
 by the common council on March 14. Afterwards the public 
 lighting commission made arrangements with the company 
 to continue its lights pending the introduction of the munici- 
 pal plant at a sum which averaged about $132 per arc lamp. 1 
 
 Agitation for municipal lighting had been begun as early as 
 January, 1890, by Mayor H. S. Pingree in his first message 
 to the common council. In each of his subsequent annual 
 messages in 1891, 1892, and 1893, the mayor again urged the 
 building of a municipal plant, and presented data and argu- 
 ments in support of this project. In 1893 a bill authorizing 
 the city to establish municipal lighting was introduced in the 
 
 STATISTICS OF PUBLIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT BY PRIVATE COMPANIES 
 
 YEAR ENDING JUNE 30 
 
 No. OF LAMPS 
 
 AMOUNT PAID 
 
 COST PER LAMP 
 
 1884 
 
 24 
 
 $ 3,649.53 
 
 $152.07 
 
 1885 
 
 300 
 
 71,982.00 
 
 239.94 
 
 1886 
 
 382 
 
 91,570.97 
 
 239.71 
 
 1887 
 
 565 
 
 115,490.26 
 
 204.41 
 
 1888 
 
 608 
 
 117,370.18 
 
 193.04 
 
 1889 
 
 702 
 
 128,068.78 
 
 182.42 
 
 1890 
 
 719 
 
 137,937.30 
 
 191.84 
 
 1891 
 
 1031 
 
 133,716.55 
 
 129.69 
 
 1892 
 
 1168 
 
 152,282.70 
 
 130.38 
 
 1893 
 
 1279 
 
 164,830.91 
 
 128.87 
 
 1894 
 
 1279 
 
 169,360.35 
 
 132.41 
 
 1895 
 
 
 153,004.36 
 
 
 1896 
 
 
 28,796.41 

 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 221 
 
 state legislature, which was passed and became law March 18. 
 April 3, under the provisions of the act, the question was sub- 
 mitted to the electors of the city, who voted 15,282 to 1245 
 in favor of a municipal plant. A public-lighting commission 
 of six members was at once appointed, and bonds to the 
 amount of $600,000 authorized, and in time sold, to defray 
 the cost of erecting the new plant. A convenient site on the 
 river front was selected for the central station, a neat but 
 not extravagant building constructed, and the necessary equip- 
 ment of machinery installed. An underground (conduit) 
 system of distribution was built for the district within a half 
 mile of the city hall, and beyond that the system of overhead 
 wires was continued. 
 
 April 1, 1895, the commission began operating that portion 
 of the new system in the district covered by the underground 
 conduits. Extensions of the service were made rapidly 
 during the following months, and by October the entire 
 public lighting was furnished by the municipal plant. There 
 was at that time 1470 arc lamps, mainly employed in street 
 lighting, and 2456 incandescent lamps in the different mu- 
 nicipal buildings. The system has continued to extend until 
 on June 30, 1905, there were 3005 arc lamps and 14,696 
 incandescent lamps in the municipal system of lighting. 
 Some arc lamps are still grouped on towers, but the greater 
 number are now distributed in single locations. 
 
 As a basis for comparison and discussion, the following 
 tables showing the cost of lighting are presented from the 
 reports of the public lighting commission. They include in 
 the cost not only the operating expenses of the plant, but 
 charges for interest on the investment, for annual deprecia- 
 tion of the plant, and for municipal taxes which would be 
 collected were the plant owned by a private corporation. 
 The items for operating expenses and interest on the invest- 
 ment present no difficult problems. The charge for lost 
 taxes is estimated by charging the regular rate of taxation 
 for city, county, and state purposes on a valuation assessed
 
 222 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 on the same basis as other similar plants in the city; the 
 assessed value of the municipal plant being about one-half 
 of the net investment. The charge for depreciation is made 
 on the net investment at the rate of three per cent, plus the 
 cost of discarded machinery. The amounts charged for these 
 two items seem to be reasonably adequate. 
 
 In some respects the figures given below vary from the 
 statements in the reports of the commission. For the first 
 two years, no attempt was made to include the items outside 
 of operating expenses necessary to calculate the annual cost 
 of the plant; and in 1897 the commission argued that the 
 only item of depreciation that should be considered was on 
 the cost of the boilers, as the rest of the plant was maintained 
 in perfect condition by expenditures for repairs. But in 
 the later reports the items of interest, depreciation, and lost 
 taxes have been considered as shown; and the corresponding 
 data for 1896 and 1897 have been compiled by the writer on 
 the same basis as the figures of the commission for subse- 
 quent years. 
 
 Again in their later reports, after estimating the cost in 
 the same form and with almost precisely the same results as 
 in the table below, the commission presents a supplementary 
 statement of items amounting to $10,000 which would reduce 
 still further the total cost. At least some of these items 
 might in fairness be deducted. The work of the commission 
 has absorbed the former municipal supervision over private 
 lighting companies, and their expenses thus include a certain 
 amount chargeable to the general expenses of the city. The 
 department also collects various sums of money for rentals 
 and sale of old materials, which reduce the net expenses, but 
 are not deducted from the total operating expenses. These 
 items, however, have not been deducted in this paper, be- 
 cause they are not given for the years before 1900, and it 
 seems better to present all the figures on the same basis. 
 The effect of this is equivalent to increasing the allowance 
 for depreciation.
 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 
 
 223 
 
 8 
 
 rH tO 
 
 1C (N 
 CD t- 
 
 OO 0010 
 
 OOtO rHO 
 
 co^o^ oo_t^ 
 
 tC 
 
 
 
 ooto t^'* 
 
 rH O O5 "* 
 OOCO COrH 
 
 N.N. * to 
 COIN co eo 
 
 l. 
 
 i 
 
 8" 8 
 
 r-Tof ofoo" 
 
 >c" 
 
 o 
 
 IN"-*" o"-*" 
 
 r^oo ic 
 coco 
 
 ^H 
 
 1H_ 00 
 
 rH 
 
 IN 
 
 fSrH^ 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 V. 
 
 
 
 
 
 00 rH 
 
 (N IN 
 
 O500 coic 
 
 co 
 
 
 
 0?^ SrH 
 
 CN O 1C 1C 
 
 *<N CD CO 
 
 ^ 
 
 rH O 
 
 
 o 
 
 ^00 CN 00 
 
 
 o 
 
 TjT TjT 
 
 CO"r-T tO"^ 
 
 oo" 
 
 
 co"ic" co 
 
 Oi 
 
 CO IN 
 
 INCO CN 
 
 oo 
 
 
 toco v. 
 
 
 o oo 
 
 
 
 
 rH 
 
 
 
 t* 
 
 '/. 
 
 TjTrH" 
 
 It 
 
 
 ^ CO 
 IN 1C 
 
 OCO O(N 
 
 i> 
 
 toco too 
 
 0000 t^(N 
 
 CN O CO CO 
 
 i>- o co co 
 
 
 (N O 
 
 Tfl rH CO O 
 
 oo 
 
 
 
 
 o" t>." 
 
 O"rn" Os"oo" 
 
 oo" 
 
 71 -H" T' -r" 
 
 co"ic" to 
 
 I _ H 
 
 t- oo 
 
 INCO N 
 
 oo 
 
 rH 0000 
 
 icco ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 CNO 
 
 rH 
 
 
 
 
 W 
 
 7.> 
 
 *" 
 
 6fc 
 
 
 (N O 
 CO CO 
 
 t^- * CO C^ 
 
 
 
 COO 1C-* 
 
 co oo to o 
 
 O to CN O 
 
 * ic oo eo 
 
 d 
 
 (N CO 
 
 o^oq^ ^ 
 
 1 
 
 rH^X '^l 1 '?. 
 
 ""I. 1 "!, eo t4 
 
 
 CN" oo" 
 
 o oo" TP"OO" 
 
 o" 
 
 CN rH CN rH 
 
 COrH CO 
 
 
 CO l~- 
 
 O5(N M 
 
 to 
 
 rH r* ic 
 
 COtN 
 
 
 05 t- 
 
 M 
 
 
 co co 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 5 
 
 co" 
 
 M 
 
 
 to to 
 
 ON C^^o 
 
 1 
 
 1COO O rH 
 
 co * ooco 
 
 t^CO rH O 
 
 t 1 * t^* co eo 
 
 ,_, 
 
 to^ oq^ 
 
 ooo coco 
 
 
 oo coo 
 
 ^ ^ t^> i^ 
 
 
 rH rH 
 
 O5 CO CN CO 
 
 CO" 
 
 of co" ic"t^ 
 
 
 
 1C IN 
 
 O5IN N 
 
 1C 
 
 t> o 
 
 COrH 
 
 1-1 
 
 00 I*. 
 
 M 
 
 
 ^ TM 
 
 rH 
 
 
 . 
 
 
 fc 
 
 co" 
 
 ** 
 
 
 SCO 
 1C 
 
 oo I**- 
 
 CO 00 CN tO 
 t>;(N (NO 
 
 i-^ to i-^co 
 
 oo 
 
 IN 
 
 co o co t^- 
 
 O CO * ic 
 
 ICCO rH O 
 
 oco oo * 
 d *' to . 
 
 
 oo o 
 
 00 rH 00 rH 
 
 O 
 
 1 1 CO f"~ rH 
 
 coo to 
 
 
 *. i 
 
 o^ (N^q^ 
 
 
 (N CO 
 
 OrH 
 
 r-l 
 
 
 
 o" 
 
 co-* 
 
 o~oo" 
 
 
 CN M* 
 
 OIN CN 
 
 
 co" 
 
 COrH 
 
 
 oo r- 
 
 
 
 rH 
 
 
 W 
 
 
 CO t^ 
 
 CO 00 rH O 
 
 OIN t^q 
 ic to * 06 
 
 q 
 *' 
 
 OOrH CO-* 
 CCrH O f- 
 
 OOO (N IN 
 
 8CN (N r)< 
 O to * 
 CDOO to 9 
 
 
 O 1C 
 
 tO ^ CO CN 
 
 
 rH -* CN t 
 
 ICrH t-. 
 
 
 oq_ r^ 
 
 to o to oo 
 
 o 
 
 oo ic 
 
 CNOO 
 
 r-l 
 
 co" i-T 
 
 to"o" CN"I^ 
 
 ^ 
 
 rHCO 
 
 rn">c" 
 
 
 rH 1C 
 
 O5CO CN 
 
 1C 
 
 co" 
 
 T^ rH 
 
 
 oo r>. 
 
 w 
 
 
 
 rH 
 
 
 W 
 
 
 (^ 
 
 
 1* 
 
 
 CO O 
 
 28 88 
 
 oo 
 
 *rH OCO 
 * O 1-HO 
 
 ooo co o 
 
 tC CO ^< M" 
 
 
 to d 
 
 co o o oo 
 
 rH 
 
 t*^ O O 1C 
 
 eo't^ co 
 
 I 
 
 rH O 
 
 o~ o" 
 
 O5"o~ CN"OO" 
 
 00 
 1C 
 
 o" 
 
 T-Teo" tc"to" 
 oco 
 
 ic^q^ 
 tc"ic" 
 
 
 O 1C 
 
 OCO CN 
 
 CO 
 
 cf 
 
 *rH 
 
 
 
 
 rH 
 
 
 rH 
 
 
 6% 
 
 
 
 
 
 1* 
 
 
 CO CD 
 
 ooo oco 
 
 CO 
 
 T}< * 00 ^ 
 
 * oo o ic 
 
 
 t- t- 
 
 CO t^ CO "* 
 
 oq 
 
 COCO <N 00 
 
 rH CD 1C 1C 
 
 
 CN co' 
 
 rH CO 1C rH 
 
 rH 
 
 IQ*Q cD^r^ 
 
 ^ IN. o 
 
 1 
 
 IN * 
 l "i. 
 
 T}< O ^00 
 rH 1C ^ O 
 
 CO 
 
 oo" 
 
 rHCO" COCO 
 T-I CO 
 
 r^oo o 
 
 rH O rH 
 ~ *" ^^ 
 
 
 (N rH 
 
 <CN N^ 
 
 CO 
 
 CN" 
 
 S-H 
 
 
 I* 
 
 * 
 
 s 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 1C 
 
 COCN -*O 
 
 (N 
 
 co to ooo 
 
 toco ^-^ .; 
 
 
 oo 
 
 CO O5 O5 O 
 
 (N 
 
 oo ic oo * 
 
 CO 00 _; C 
 
 1. 
 
 B 
 
 Q 
 
 
 d 
 
 * 'J' CO >C 
 
 *' 1C d fc. IN 
 
 SH 
 
 CO 
 
 
 rH 
 
 rH CN 00 t*~ 
 
 ooco .5 aj ic 
 
 E 
 
 rH 
 
 
 CN 
 
 O t"~ 
 
 O CN ^, C-iO 
 
 00 O 
 
 o" 
 
 cN 00 ^ ^ 
 
 o" 
 
 r-^rH 
 
 "o" to oo (4 
 
 rt S 
 
 
 OOrH 1-H 
 
 <N 
 
 CN 
 
 rH rH Oq 
 
 a 
 
 CO 
 
 w 
 
 M 
 
 <@ 
 
 
 S * 00 
 1-- O 
 
 EAR ENDING 
 JUNE 30 
 
 1 Jji I* '* ' 11 1 ' "^ -i 
 
 8 do ^ rc-n ' -- ^ min m 3 ' ' 
 
 ii i jj jf if y i ii jii jiii f | 
 
 r* 
 
 5J HrS O* rSft 3 rlrl ^ < rS Q < rS OQ
 
 224 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The first and clearest deduction from these figures is that 
 the municipal plant has furnished public lighting to Detroit 
 for a much smaller expenditure than would have been re- 
 quired under any alternative presented in the bid of the pri- 
 vate company in 1893. The lowest rate proposed by the 
 private company was $102.20 per arc lamp for a ten-year 
 contract. The municipal plant furnished lights at appre- 
 ciably less than this figure from the outset; and the cost 
 has fallen steadily until for the past five years it has been 
 less than two-thirds of the minimum price demanded by the 
 company. The direct financial results have thus fully jus- 
 tified the city of Detroit in establishing a municipal system 
 of electric lighting. 
 
 If, however, it is urged that the depreciation allowances 
 are not sufficient, it can still be demonstrated beyond question 
 that the first decade of municipal lighting was a financial suc- 
 cess for Detroit. In the whole period of ten years there was 
 expended for the plant and improvements $1,1 12,455, and for 
 operating expenses $1,059,996, a gross total expenditure of 
 $2,172,451. If it should be assumed that in 1905 the plant was 
 entirely useless and its value wiped out, the total cost of light- 
 ing for the decade was $87.63 per arc light per year, as com- 
 pared with the lowest contract offered in 1895 of $102.20. 
 On this basis the city had saved $460,000 in the ten years. 
 
 Moreover, other beneficial results have followed from the 
 new system. The rapid extension in the number of lights 
 may be ascribed to the reduction in cost, which has allowed 
 a smaller total expenditure to provide a large increase in 
 the amount of lighting. But along with the increase in 
 number of lamps, there has gone a noticeable improvement 
 in the quality of the service, as indicated by the great decrease 
 in number of lamps reported out by the police. In 1893^, 
 under the contract system, the total number of lamp-hours 
 reported out was 86,426; since the municipal works have 
 been in full operation, the largest number of lamp-hours 
 out in one year has been 7465.
 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 225 
 
 It must not be supposed that the conclusions thus far 
 reached offer any basis for a generalization in favor of mu- 
 nicipal lighting. The only fact shown is that Detroit has in 
 the ten years secured better and cheaper lighting under its 
 municipal system than could have been secured by a contract 
 made in 1893. May it not be, however, that these results 
 have been gained through improvements in electric lighting 
 since 1893 which are not likely to be duplicated; so that 
 while compared with the alternative of 1893 Detroit has 
 gained, a private company might now offer lower prices than 
 the city is paying. A decisive answer to this query is not 
 easy to find. But it is possible to obtain some light on the 
 subject by comparing the cost of Detroit lighting with the 
 prices charged by private companies for public lighting in 
 other cities. There is an abundant supply of material for 
 making such a comparison in the report of the Commissioner 
 of Labor on Water, Gas., and Electric Lighting Plants pub- 
 lished in 1899. The statistics given in this report are for 
 various dates from 1897 to 1899; and the Detroit report for 
 the year ending June 30, 1898, will correspond most nearly 
 to these varying dates. 
 
 For the year 1897-8, the cost of the Detroit municipal 
 plant was at the rate of $83.46 for each arc lamp for 3786 
 hours in the year, or $.049 per kilowatt hour. An examina- 
 tion of the summary tables in the Labor Commissioners' 
 report shows that no group of private companies charged 
 for public lighting less than $.0514 per kilowatt hour; and 
 that, when the hours of service are considered, no group 
 charged so low a price per arc lamp as the cost in Detroit. 
 From the detailed tables showing the statistics for each plant, 
 the following table has been compiled including all the pri- 
 vate plants reported which furnished 500 or more arc lamps 
 for public lighting:
 
 226 
 
 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTKATION 
 
 STATISTICS OF PUBLIC LIGHTING BY PRIVATE 
 CORPORATIONS 
 
 PLANT 
 NUMBER 
 
 NUMBER OP 
 PUBLIC ARC 
 LAMPS 
 
 HOURS OF 
 SERVICE 
 
 PRICE PER 
 LAMP 
 PER YEAR 
 
 PRICE PER 
 KILOWATT 
 HOUR' 
 
 TOTAL 
 
 INVESTMENT IN 
 PLANT 
 
 889 
 
 860 
 
 4000 
 
 $147.93 
 
 $.0800 
 
 $609,129 
 
 893 
 
 513 
 
 3900 
 
 100.00 
 
 .0838 
 
 473,621 
 
 915 
 
 916 
 
 2216 
 
 74.50 
 
 .0731 
 
 450,000 
 
 918 
 
 1243 
 
 3988 
 
 120.34 
 
 .0631 
 
 664,267 
 
 922 
 
 984 
 
 3988 
 
 91.25 
 
 .0416 
 
 1,752,552 
 
 924 
 
 538 
 
 4000 
 
 138.70 
 
 .0771 
 
 875,335 
 
 925 
 
 510 
 
 4650 
 
 146.00 
 
 .0654 
 
 1,591,801 
 
 931 
 
 1173 
 
 3000 
 
 85.00 
 
 .0630 
 
 800,847 
 
 932 
 
 626 
 
 3960 
 
 85.00 
 
 .0477 
 
 1,170,859 
 
 933 
 
 1279 
 
 4000 
 
 91.25 
 
 .0507 
 
 1,250,000 
 
 934 
 
 860 
 
 3953 
 
 104.84 
 
 .0479 
 
 2,600,000 
 
 935 
 
 674 
 
 3878 
 
 75.00 
 
 .0569 
 
 836,157 
 
 936 
 
 2500 
 
 4000 
 
 100.00 
 
 .0500 
 
 1,975,000 
 
 937 
 
 927 
 
 3888 
 
 93.24 
 
 .0500 
 
 2,107,660 
 
 939 
 
 800 
 
 2685 
 
 103.00 
 
 .0833 
 
 1,341,100 
 
 940 
 
 958 
 
 3966 
 
 100.38 
 
 .0634 
 
 1,845,569 
 
 941 
 
 1390 
 
 4000 
 
 127.50 
 
 .0708 
 
 4,157,354 
 
 942 
 
 830 
 
 4000 
 
 116.27 
 
 .0781 
 
 850,000 
 
 943 
 
 702 
 
 3855 
 
 102.70 
 
 .0595 
 
 1,475,000 
 
 944 
 
 3647 
 
 4000 
 
 97.97 
 
 .0500 
 
 2,040,000 
 
 947 
 
 652 
 
 3210 
 
 176.55 
 
 .1273 
 
 2,773,904 
 
 948 
 
 2276 
 
 3940 
 
 127.31 
 
 .0630 
 
 3,145,541 
 
 949 
 
 1216 
 
 4000 
 
 86.09 
 
 .0476 
 
 2,683,875 
 
 951 
 
 2072 
 
 4000 
 
 96.00 
 
 .0505 
 
 1,961,551 
 
 It will be noticed that four of the twenty-four plants fur- 
 nished lights at lower prices per kilowatt hour than the cost 
 in Detroit for 1898, and that five others furnished lights at 
 prices but slightly in excess; while in the remaining thirteen 
 cases the prices are distinctly higher than the cost in Detroit. 
 
 1 It should be noted that the figures of cost given in Tables 10 and 11 
 of the Commissioner of Labor's Report for municipal plants cannot be 
 compared with the prices charged by private companies, given in the 
 same tables. The cost for municipal plants does not include estimates 
 for lost taxes or interest (see p. 549 of Report); and in some cases no 
 adequate charge is made for depreciation. The estimated charges for 
 lost taxes and interest are presented in Table 8; and it is difficult to 
 understand why, with this data at "hand, the serious error should have 
 been made of leaving it out of consideration in computing the cost per 
 arc light and per kilowatt hour. 
 
 Note in above table that the private plants with lowest prices are 
 all plants with much larger investment than the Detroit plant.
 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 227 
 
 These facts indicate that the city of Detroit has secured its 
 public lighting through its municipal plant not only for much 
 less than could have been obtained by contract in 1893, but 
 also on terms which compare favorably with the lowest 
 prices charged by private companies in other cities. It can- 
 not be claimed, however, that the Detroit municipal rate 
 shows any large advantage over the lowest private rates, 
 while in one city a private company furnishes public lights 
 at a price one-sixth lower than the Detroit lights cost. It 
 should be remembered that the private companies have an 
 important advantage in supplying electricity to private con- 
 sumers within the same area as the public lighting, thus 
 securing the economies of manufacture and distribution on 
 a larger scale. If the Detroit municipal plant supplied the 
 private demand, undoubtedly the cost of city lighting would 
 be still further reduced. But viewing the existing situation, 
 the fact of some private rates lower than the Detroit munici- 
 pal rate must be recognized. 
 
 This comparison has been made on the basis of the cost of 
 Detroit lighting for 1898. If the striking reductions in the 
 Detroit figures since that time have been in large measure 
 confined to this city, the cost of lighting has been reduced 
 below the price charged by any private company in the above 
 table, and the success of the municipal plant is strongly em- 
 phasized. It is probable, however, that at least some im- 
 portant reductions have been made at the same time in the 
 cost and price of public lighting in other cities; and in the 
 absence of definite data of recent date, for any large number 
 of cities, it is not possible to make accurate deductions as to 
 the comparative significance of the cost of Detroit lighting 
 for recent years. It may be noted, however, that as late as 
 1902 the city of Buffalo secured a reduction in the price of 
 light to $75 or 20 per cent more than the total estimated 
 cost in Detroit, although the Niagara Falls power should 
 make the cost much less at Buffalo. 
 
 The entire responsibility for the management of the Detroit
 
 228 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 lighting plant rests with the public lighting commission ; and 
 this paper would be incomplete without noting the character 
 and methods of the commission, which have been essential 
 factors in the success of the municipal plant. The com- 
 mission consists of six members appointed by the mayor of 
 the city with the consent of the council. These serve without 
 salary for six-year terms, one member retiring each year. 
 This organization offers certain advantages. The gradual 
 renewal of the membership serves to insure a continuous 
 tradition and a steady policy in the management, while the 
 absence of salary probably lessens the pressure of profes- 
 sional place hunters for appointments. But it is not every- 
 where an easy matter to find efficient commissioners for such 
 boards; and the Detroit experiment has been highly favored 
 in securing as members of the commission active business 
 men who have been both able and willing to devote a large 
 amount of time to this work. The character of the members 
 can best be illustrated by the methods adopted. 
 
 In the first place, the commissioners take an active per- 
 sonal part in the management. During recent years the 
 work of making purchases and contracts for supplies has 
 been performed directly by committees of the board; and 
 the savings made by this system account in large part for the 
 reduction in operating expenses during these years. In the 
 second place, the other expenditures have been throughout 
 on a conservative and business basis. No expensive build- 
 ings have been constructed, and no extravagant salaries are 
 paid. The general superintendent receives $2000 a year, 
 two other officers have $1200 a year, and no others over 
 $1000 a year. Yet the wages of the men are as high as in any 
 business concern, and the eight-hour day is in force. In the 
 third place, the tenure of positions is dependent solely upon 
 efficiency, and a system of promotion in service according 
 to merit and fitness for the work is employed. 
 
 In brief, this honorary commission manages the municipal 
 lighting plant precisely as a board of directors would conduct
 
 MUNICIPAL ELECTRIC LIGHTING IN DETROIT 229 
 
 the affairs of a well-managed private corporation. Directors 
 usually have a large pecuniary interest in the corporations, 
 which explains their active work for its financial success. 
 Unsalaried boards of managers have, however, proven effec- 
 tive in the administration of educational and charitable 
 institutions, both public and private, mainly on account of 
 the philanthropic interest attached to the work. In our 
 national administration, too, the dignity of a position in the 
 President's cabinet secures for the direction of the army, 
 navy, and post-office, men whose services command in the 
 business world many times the salary they receive from the 
 government. A city which finds men willing to perform 
 similar honorary service in the administration of a purely 
 economic function has certainly made long strides toward 
 the realization of municipal ideals.
 
 XII 
 
 ON April 2, 1907, the people of Chicago, by a decisive vote, 
 agreed to certain ordinances which mark a turning-point 
 in the street railway history of that city, and provide at 
 least a temporary settlement to a controversy that dates 
 back for more than forty years, and has been actively con- 
 tested for the past decade. The story of this long-con- 
 tinued struggle is important, not only because Chicago is the 
 second largest city in the country, but also as part of the 
 larger contest that is being carried on, more or less openly, 
 in most of our American cities. And the arrangements in 
 these Chicago ordinances set a new standard in the relations 
 between street railway companies and public authorities 
 that will have an effect throughout the United States. 
 
 In relating this story, it will be necessary, in order to under- 
 stand some of the most recent events, to begin with the 
 earliest street railways in Chicago. But the early history 
 and the first stages of the more active contest will be dis- 
 cussed briefly. The greater part of this paper will deal with 
 the events of the past ten years, and more particularly with 
 the final steps and the terms of the settlement that has been 
 made. The contest has important political aspects; and to 
 some these have seemed more important than the trans- 
 portation problems. But in this account, while some at- 
 tention will be given to the political bearings, the emphasis 
 will be laid on the legal, economic, and administrative features. 
 
 The earliest attempts to 'furnish cheap local transporta- 
 tion in Chicago, as in other cities, was by means of omni- 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Quarterly Journal of Economics, XXI, 371 
 (May, 1907). 
 
 230
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 231 
 
 buses operating on regular lines of travel. The first omnibus 
 line of which there is any record was established in 1850, 
 when the city had a population of 28,000, and ran from the 
 business centre to Lincoln Park. Other lines were established 
 in the years following; and by 1855 there were all together 
 ten omnibus lines in operation, covering an aggregate dis- 
 tance of 18| miles. At first each line was begun by different 
 managers; but in 1855 the operation of several lines was 
 consolidated under the management of Franklin Parmalee 
 & Co. For a few years more the omnibus traffic con- 
 tinued to develop; but with the opening of street rail- 
 ways it rapidly declined. By 1861 only two omnibus lines 
 were in operation; and by 1865 all had been discontinued. 1 
 More recently a few new omnibus lines have been established, 
 but these form a negligible factor in the means of passenger 
 transportation in the city of Chicago. 
 
 A local student has discovered a newspaper notice of a local 
 grant authorizing the construction of a street railway in 
 Chicago as early as 1854. And there is official record of a 
 council ordinance of 1856, granting a street railway franchise. 
 But no action was taken on either of these ; and the latter was 
 forfeited by the failure to secure the required consent of the 
 owners of adjacent property. The first effective ordinance 
 for the construction and operation of street railways in 
 Chicago was passed by the city council, August 16, 1858. 
 As the terms of this ordinance were involved in the recent 
 litigation and settlement, it is of especial importance to under- 
 stand its contents and significance. It authorized a group 
 of individuals including Franklin Parmalee, the head of 
 the partnership then operating the principal omnibus lines 
 to construct railway tracks on certain streets on the south 
 and west of the Chicago River, and to operate cars thereon 
 "with animal power only" for a period of twenty-five years, 
 and until the city should "elect to purchase" the plant and 
 
 1 George B. Goodwin, Chicago Street Railways. A manuscript essay 
 in the possession of Professor J. H. Gray, of Northwestern University.
 
 232 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 equipment. A maximum fare of five cents was specified; 
 and the grantees were to pay one-third of the cost of grading 
 and paving streets. The council reserved the right to regu- 
 late the rate of speed and the time of running cars. Under 
 this ordinance tracks were laid, and the first line opened in 
 April, 1859. 
 
 Meanwhile a question had been raised as to the legal 
 authority of the city council to grant such a franchise. To 
 settle these doubts and to incorporate the grantees, a special 
 act of the Illinois legislature was passed on February 16, 
 1859, incorporating the grantees under the city ordinance 
 as the Chicago City Railway Company, for a period of twenty- 
 five years, and authorizing the construction and operation 
 of street railways upon terms and conditions provided by 
 the common council. Authority was also given to extend 
 the lines to any part of Cook County, by the exercise of the 
 power of eminent domain, or with the assent of the super- 
 visor of any township for laying tracks in the highways. 
 The same powers were granted to another group of individuals 
 as the North Chicago City Railway Company, for the north 
 division of the city and county. 
 
 On May 23, 1859, the council passed ordinances granting 
 rights in important streets to both of these companies. The 
 ordinance to the Chicago City Railway Company was, in 
 substance, a reaffirmation of the ordinance of 1858, on the 
 basis of the act of the legislature. The ordinance to the 
 North Chicago City Railway Company for the first time gave 
 that company rights in specified streets, and differed from 
 the ordinance of 1858 in limiting the grant to the term of 
 twenty-five years "and no longer." 
 
 On February 21, 1861, the Illinois legislature passed an 
 act which incorporated the Chicago West Division Railway 
 Company, with the same powers as the two previously estab- 
 lished companies, but required the consent of the North 
 Chicago Company before the construction of any tracks in 
 the north division, and authorized the new company to
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 233 
 
 acquire any of the rights of the City Railway Company. 
 In the summer of 1863 the City Railway Company trans- 
 ferred to the West Division Company control over its lines in 
 the west division of the city. 
 
 These measures, which form the first stage in the develop- 
 ment of the street railway system of Chicago, have been 
 held by the United States Supreme Court to have established 
 clearly the policy of municipal control, and in particular to 
 recognize the right of the city to fix the term during which 
 the streets might be occupied by street railway companies. 
 
 That it was the intention of the legislature to give effect to the right 
 of municipal control in the act under consideration [that of 1859] is 
 shown in its confirmation of terms already fixed by contract between 
 the city and the companies. As to the future, companies were to have 
 no right to the use and occupancy of the streets until they should 
 obtain from the city council authority to that end, under contracts to 
 be agreed upon as to terms and conditions. A more comprehensive 
 plan of securing the city in the control of the use of the streets for 
 railway purposes could hardly be devised. 
 
 It thus clearly appears, at least up to the passage of the act of 1865, 
 that legislation upon the subject recognized and enforced the right and 
 authority of the city to fix the term during which the streets might 
 be occupied by street railway companies. The legislature had con- 
 firmed the ordinance of the city fixing the term at twenty-five years 
 and until the city should see fit to purchase the property of the railway 
 company. It had required the companies to obtain the authority of 
 the city before using the streets, such use to be upon terms and con- 
 ditions, and with such rights and privileges as the city had or might 
 thereafter prescribe by contract with the companies. 1 
 
 From time to time the council passed other ordinances 
 authorizing new lines of railway tracks and making minor 
 changes in previous grants. In most cases these ordinances 
 contained a definite time limit. Under them additional 
 lines were built ; and by 1865 there were forty miles of street 
 railways in the city. 
 
 In that year another act dealing with horse railways in 
 
 1 Blair v. Chicago, 201 U.S. 400.
 
 234 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Chicago was passed by the legislature, which vitally affected 
 the situation, laid the basis for the extreme claims of the 
 companies in the recent litigation, and more than anything 
 else has been responsible for the long agitation in reference 
 to street railways in that city. This act, passed on Febru- 
 ary 6, 1865, was amendatory of the previous acts of 1859 and 
 1861. It clearly extended the corporate lives of the com- 
 panies to a period of ninety-nine years from the dates of the 
 original acts. It also added, to the section authorizing the 
 construction and operation of railways on the terms pro- 
 vided by the council, the following confused and ambiguous 
 clause : 
 
 and any and all acts or deeds of transfer of rights, privileges, or fran- 
 chises, between the corporations in said several acts named, or any 
 two of them, and all contracts, stipulations, licenses, and undertakings, 
 made, entered into, or given ; and as made or amended by and between 
 the said common council and any one or more of the said corporations, 
 respecting the location, use or exclusion of railways in or upon the 
 streets or any of them, of said city, shall be deemed and held and 
 continued in force during the life hereof as valid and effectual, to all 
 intents and purposes, as if made a part, and the same are hereby made 
 a part of said several acts. 
 
 Before this measure was enacted, it was strongly opposed 
 in the city of Chicago, and a petition, signed by 9000 citizens, 
 was presented against its passage. When the bill reached 
 Governor Oglesby, he refused to sign it, and returned it to 
 the legislature with a vigorous message in opposition. But 
 the plans of the companies had been well laid, and the bill 
 was promptly passed over the governor's veto, by a vote 
 of 18 to 5 in the Senate and 55 to 23 in the House. 
 
 Under this act the companies have claimed that their 
 franchises were extended to a period of ninety-nine years 
 from 1859 and 1861. And they asserted this claim, not only 
 in reference to grants made -before the passage of the act of 
 1865, but also in reference to subsequent grants. On the 
 other hand, the city always denied the validity of these claims. 
 But for forty years the matter was not brought into the
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 235 
 
 courts where the precise effect of the act could receive a 
 judicial interpretation. 
 
 However the act of 1865 might be interpreted, the pro- 
 test against its obvious intent to assert the authority of the 
 legislature in local matters soon led to a return to the earlier 
 policy of local control and short-term franchises. The new 
 constitution of Illinois, adopted in 1870, contained a pro- 
 vision prohibiting the legislature from granting street rail- 
 way rights in any city, town, or incorporated village 
 without requiring the consent of the local authorities. 
 This policy was continued in the general act of 1872 for 
 the incorporation of cities, which required all street rail- 
 way franchises granted thereafter to be limited to twenty 
 years. This provision became applicable to Chicago when 
 that city adopted the act in 1875. The same end had 
 been secured' by a provision in the Horse and Dummy Act 
 of 1874, also limiting future street railway grants to 
 twenty years. And various franchises were granted from 
 time to time under these acts for the further extension 
 of the Chicago street railways. 
 
 Under the provisions of the first ordinances and legisla- 
 tive acts, the grants made in 1858 should have expired, or 
 at least have been terminable in 1883. At that time the 
 questions were extensively discussed, and, if claims had 
 been pressed either by the city or the companies, a deter- 
 mination might have been reached. The Citizens' Associa- 
 tion appointed a committee to investigate the matter. Two 
 of the three members reported that the original contract 
 made by the city in 1858 was ultra vires and void, and that 
 the companies held their rights under the act of 1865. The 
 third member (George F. Harding) argued that the act of 
 1859 had confirmed the grants made the year before, and 
 that the act of 1865 simply extended the lives of the cor- 
 porations, holding that any extension of the franchises 
 provided by the act was void as an impairment of the con- 
 tract previously made.
 
 236 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 In view of these circumstances a temporary compromise 
 was effected. The city council in July, 1883, passed an 
 ordinance extending the term of all existing franchises for 
 twenty years, and providing that neither this grant nor its 
 acceptance by the companies should alter the existing rights, 
 duties, and obligations of either party. By this means the 
 controversy over the ninety-nine-year act was postponed 
 until the expiration of this grant in 1903. In the same year 
 (1883) a new company, the Chicago Passenger Railway 
 Company, had been incorporated and received franchises 
 for twenty years to build and operate additional lines on the 
 west side. 
 
 II 
 
 Until 1880 the street railways of Chicago had been operated 
 with horses, and the business developed had not been suffi- 
 cient to attract the attention of large financial promoters. 
 But soon after this date there was introduced, first, cable 
 traction, and later, electric power. These changes of motive 
 power were made without any new grant from the city 
 council or the legislature, although the earlier franchises 
 had been given distinctly for railways to be operated 
 only by animal power. And in connection with the 
 new methods of traction and the reconstruction of the 
 lines there appeared on the scene new managers, new 
 financial interests, and striking methods of speculative 
 financiering. 
 
 Cable traction was first established in 1881 on the most 
 important lines of the City Railway Company on the south 
 side. In a few years a large proportion of the lines of this 
 company had been converted to the new system. After 
 1890 electric power was introduced on many of the lines. 
 In connection with these improvements large issues of stocks 
 and bonds were made from time to time. In 1880 the total 
 capital liabilities had been $1,500,000 in stock. By 1897 
 there were outstanding $16,600,000 in stock and bonds,
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 237 
 
 against which the plant and equipment on the books of the 
 company represented an investment of about $11,600,000.* 
 
 But these transactions appear small in comparison with 
 those for the north and west side lines. Here the original 
 companies were dilatory in taking steps to introduce the 
 new methods, and no active steps were taken until 1886. 
 Beginning in that year, Mr. Charles T. Yerkes, a broker 
 who had recently come to Chicago from Philadelphia, with 
 the assistance of Messrs. Elkins and Widener and other 
 Philadelphia capitalists, secured control of a majority of the 
 stock of the North Chicago and West Division companies. 
 Two new companies were organized which leased the lines 
 of the original companies and also those of the Chicago 
 Passenger Railway. New securities were issued, and physical 
 improvements, reconstruction, and extensions were carried 
 out. As a result, at the end of ten years (in 1897) the total 
 capital liabilities of the north and west side lines had been 
 increased from less than $8,000,000 2 to $58,700,000. The 
 cost value of the plant and equipment at the latter date, 
 according to the books of the companies, was $29,750,000, 
 and this included a large profit to inside construction com- 
 panies formed by the leading capitalists controlling the 
 companies owning and operating the lines. 
 
 Combining the financial operations of all these companies, 
 the total capital liabilities had been increased from $9,500,000 
 to more than $75,000,000 in 1897, while the book cost of 
 construction had been but little over $40,000,000. 3 
 
 In carrying out his extensive schemes, Mr. Yerkes had 
 deemed it advisable to exercise an active but, so far as possible, 
 a secret influence in political affairs. He became the domi- 
 nant factor in nominating conventions, and had control over 
 both city and state governments, so far at least as his busi- 
 
 1 " Report of Investigation by the Civic Federation " in Municipal 
 Affairs, V, 439. 
 
 3 Even this was much in excess of the cost of construction up to that 
 time. 
 
 3 Op. cit.
 
 238 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ness interests were concerned. And the period of his domi- 
 nance, in the early nineties, marks the deepest degradation 
 of both the city council of Chicago and the state legislature 
 of Illinois. His success up to this point encouraged him to 
 enter on more far-reaching plans. But these very plans 
 served at last to arouse the public opinion of the community 
 and to inaugurate an effective movement for the betterment 
 of political conditions both in city and state. 
 
 In 1895 bills were introduced and passed in the legislature 
 to confer new franchise rights more valuable than could be 
 granted by the council. These were, however, blocked by 
 the veto of Governor Altgeld. Two years later, with a more 
 pliant governor in the executive chair, the attempt was 
 renewed. A series of bills known as the Humphrey Bills 
 were introduced, conferring franchises for fifty years with 
 no safeguards for the public interests and no compensation 
 for what were now clearly seen to be privileges of immense 
 financial value. But public sentiment in Chicago was now 
 thoroughly aroused, and was vigorously expressed in a series 
 of public meetings. The protests were carried to the legisla- 
 ture, and were, in part, effective by preventing the passage 
 of the original bills. There was enacted, however, with the 
 approval of the governor, the Allen law, authorizing city 
 councils to grant street railway franchises for fifty-year 
 periods and in other ways strengthening the position of the 
 companies. 1 
 
 A short time before this the city council of Chicago would 
 have readily granted franchises under the Allen law. But 
 in 1896 the Municipal Voters' League had been organized, 
 and had already improved the general character of the council 
 by securing the election of better men. Other members 
 who might have been subject to improper influences knew 
 that their actions were more closely watched than formerly. 
 The attitude of Mayor Carter Harrison, Jr., in opposition 
 to any grant under the Allen law, also aided in preventing 
 
 1 J. H. Gray, Quarterly Journal of Economics, October, 1897.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 239 
 
 any action. Not only was no grant made, but it was clearly 
 indicated that no further grants would be made until that 
 law was repealed. In the legislative elections of 1898 the 
 vote on the Allen law was made an issue in many districts, 
 and a large number of members who had voted for the law 
 were defeated for renomination or reelection. And the 
 law was promptly repealed by the legislature of 1899. 
 
 At the April municipal election of 1899, following the 
 repeal of the Allen law, Mayor Harrison was reelected for 
 a second term; and, mainly through the work of the Voters' 
 League, the council had now a clear majority of members 
 that could be trusted to vote against any franchise that did 
 not protect the interests of the community. Under these 
 circumstances, Mr. Yerkes decided to retire. The Chicago 
 Union Traction Company was organized by the Elkins- 
 Widener-Whitney syndicate, which took over Mr. Yerkes's 
 holdings and entered into new leases with the underlying 
 companies to operate both the north and west side lines. 
 This eliminated Mr. Yerkes from the situation, but the process 
 of financial manipulation continued. 
 
 At the same time the companies definitely adopted the 
 policy of refusing to make further improvements in the 
 service on the ground that capital could not be secured 
 without additional franchises. The cable lines were now 
 clearly antiquated, the track and rolling stock were allowed 
 to deteriorate, with the obvious purpose of forcing the grant 
 of a new franchise on terms to be dictated by the companies. 
 Later events showed clearly that there was no justification 
 for the plea that improvements could not be made without 
 new grants. For in two of the three divisions of the city 
 the companies, under their original franchises, could not be 
 dispossessed until they were paid full value for their plant 
 and equipment. Moreover, the companies maintained at 
 the same time their claims under the ninety-nine-year act, 
 and on the basis of these claims and the constantly increasing 
 traffic were actively engaged in floating new securities and
 
 240 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 piling up the obligations on their rapidly deteriorating equip- 
 ment. An elaborate investigation, made under the direction 
 of the Civic Federation in 1901, showed that the aggregate 
 capital liabilities of the companies had then a face value of 
 $117,000,000 and a market value of $120,000,000, an 
 increase of more than $40,000,000 since 1897. At the same 
 time the original cost value of assets was $56,000,000, or but 
 $15,000,000 more than in 1897. Making conservative allow- 
 ances for depreciation, the market value of the assets was but 
 $45,840,000; and if the inter-company obligations repre- 
 senting no physical property were deducted, the net value 
 of the physical property was only $34,750,000. 1 
 
 Ill 
 
 In the early stages of the contest with Mr. Yerkes and 
 the companies, the energies of public-spirited citizens and 
 the local authorities had been directed to the negative task 
 of defeating the plans of the former for extending and making 
 more secure their control over the local transportation ser- 
 vice and the political situation. The development of a con- 
 structive policy was a task of even greater difficulty, and one 
 that has taken a good many years to bring to its present 
 outcome. The first step in this direction was the appoint- 
 ment by the council, late in 1897, of a special committee to 
 collect and collate information on the subject of street rail- 
 ways. This committee in March of the following year sub- 
 mitted a detailed report on the franchises, operation, and 
 finances of the various companies, and on the wages of em- 
 ployees and the conditions of employment. It made no 
 specific recommendations; 2 but, nevertheless, this report, 
 known as the Harlan report, from Alderman John Maynard 
 Harlan, the first member of the committee, forms the starting- 
 point for the policy later developed. 
 
 1 M. R. Maltbie, in Municipal Affairs, V, 450. 
 
 2 Report of the Special Committee of the City Council of Chicago on 
 Street Railway Franchises and Operations, March 28, 1898.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 241 
 
 Another step was taken in December, 1899, when the 
 city council passed resolutions creating a street railway 
 commission, which was in fact a committee of the council 
 to examine the feasibility of municipal ownership of street 
 railways and also the terms and conditions on which new 
 franchises might be granted. This commission, of which 
 Alderman Milton J. Foreman was chairman, submitted its 
 report in December, 1900, known commonly in Chicago as 
 the Sikes report, from Mr. George C. Sikes, the secretary 
 of the commission. This report favored, among other things, 
 the unification of management of all street railways in the 
 city, the prohibition of overcapitalization, publicity in the 
 conduct of the business, and the reservation of broad powers 
 of control by the city in any future franchises. It also 
 urged that the city should secure from the legislature an 
 enabling act authorizing municipal ownership, as a reserve 
 power to place the city in a better position to make terms 
 with private corporations. 1 A bill to carry out these rec- 
 ommendations was submitted with the report, providing 
 for a popular referendum on street railway franchises, au- 
 thorizing municipal ownership, and after a referendum 
 vote municipal operation. The bill was introduced in the 
 legislature in 1901, but was not reported by the committees 
 of either House. 
 
 Carrying out one of the recommendations of the com- 
 mission, the city council in 1901 created a special committee 
 on local transportation. After the election of April, 1901, 2 
 this committee was made a permanent standing committee; 
 and this committee, with changes in its membership from 
 time to time, has had charge of the subsequent development 
 of the municipal policy. As a result of its first year's work, 
 the committee formulated and submitted to the council 
 an outline of the provisions that should be included in any 
 
 1 Report of the Street Railway Commission to the City Council of 
 Chicago, December, 1900. 
 
 2 At which Mayor Harrison was elected for a third term. 
 
 B
 
 242 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 franchise renewal ordinance. This outline specified that 
 such a franchise should be granted for twenty years, with a 
 proviso that the city might purchase at any time after the 
 expiration of the first ten years of the grant. It further 
 provided that the companies should waive absolutely all 
 claims under the ninety-nine-year act. And it reserved to the 
 city council large powers of control, and required the con- 
 struction of underground trolley lines in the business centre 
 of the city. Nothing definite, however, was accomplished. 
 The companies were not ready to accept these terms. And 
 the city authorities were also willing to wait until the expi- 
 ration of the twenty-year extension ordinance in 1903. 
 
 While the official authorities of the city were thus pre- 
 paring for a renewal of the franchises, popular sentiment 
 was advancing more rapidly in favor of the policy of mu- 
 nicipal ownership. And the strength of this sentiment was 
 clearly shown at a popular referendum in April, 1902. This 
 vote was taken under an Illinois statute of 1901, known as 
 the Public Opinion Law, under which, on petition of 25 per 
 cent of the registered voters, questions of public policy may 
 be submitted to popular vote. These votes have no legal 
 binding effect, but are merely an indication of popular opinion. 
 Before the spring election of 1902 the Referendum League 
 secured the required number of signatures to a petition call- 
 ing for a vote on the questions of municipal ownership of 
 street railways and lighting plants and the direct nomina- 
 tion of candidates for city officers. At the election the total 
 vote cast for city officers was about 200,000, or a little more 
 than half of the vote cast at the preceding presidential elec- 
 tion. The vote on the questions of public policy was about 
 170,000, and was about seven to one in the affirmative on 
 each of the three propositions. In regard to municipal 
 ownership of street railways the actual vote was 142,826 in 
 favor and 27,998 against. 
 
 There has been much difference of opinion as to the signifi- 
 cance of this vote. On its face it indicated an overwhelm-
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 243 
 
 ing popular demand. But it has been pointed out that the 
 vote in favor of municipal ownership represented little more 
 than a third of the total registered voters, and it has also 
 been urged that it simply expressed the general hostility to 
 the traction companies that had been aroused by their poor 
 service and policy of exploitation. However the vote may be 
 interpreted, there can be no question that it gave a renewed 
 impetus to the demand for an act authorizing municipal 
 ownership. To this end efforts were next directed, and in 
 these efforts there were united both those who favored the 
 actual establishment of a municipal system and those who 
 desired the authority as a means of negotiating with the 
 companies. 
 
 At the beginning of the legislative session of 1903 the 
 prospects for any legislation opposed by the street railway 
 companies were far from bright. Especially in the organiza- 
 tion of the house of representatives, the election of speaker, 
 and the appointment of the committee on transportation, 
 it was indicated that the street railway companies were 
 working in harmony with William C. Lorimer, the boss of 
 the Republican machine in Chicago, and with Governor 
 Yates. Nevertheless, it was decided to make the attempt. 
 An agreement was reached to support a measure drafted by 
 Walter L. Fisher, secretary of the Municipal Voters' League, 
 and introduced by Senator Muller, after whom it was named. 
 This bill was strongly supported, not only by Mayor Harrison 
 and the city council, but also by Graeme Stewart, Republican 
 candidate for mayor in the election campaign of that spring, 
 by John Maynard Harlan, who had been Mr. Stewart's active 
 opponent for the nomination, by the Voters' League and other 
 organizations, and by the newspaper press of Chicago, with 
 the exception of the Inter-Ocean, which, it was known, had 
 been purchased by the street railway interests. As a result 
 of this influence, the Muller bill passed the Senate immedi- 
 ately after the municipal election in April ; * but it seems to 
 
 1 Mayor Harrison was reflected for a fourth term.
 
 244 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 have been clearly the intention to defeat the measure in the 
 House. 
 
 The contest culminated in a dramatic situation of the 
 highest intensity. The House committee on transporta- 
 tion, to which the Muller bill was referred, prepared a sub- 
 stitute measure, and a strong effort was made to induce at 
 least some of the Chicago supporters of the Muller bill to 
 accept this substitute. 1 When this offer was refused, the 
 House leaders decided to resort to extreme measures, as it 
 was known that the Democrats in the House would unite 
 with the Independent Republicans in favor of the senate 
 bill. The house committee presented its substitute report, 
 and, in the face of a demand for a roll-call from two-thirds 
 of the members, the speaker put a series of motions, and 
 declared them carried, whereby the substitute bill was re- 
 corded as having passed its third reading. Had this result 
 stood, a conference committee would have been necessary; 
 and so near was the end of the session that either the sub- 
 stitute bill or no legislation would have been enacted. 
 
 But the party leaders had overreached themselves. When, 
 through fear of personal violence, the speaker declared the 
 House adjourned, and retired in haste to consult with the 
 governor and his friends, ninety-seven of the one hundred and 
 fifty-three members of the House remained in their places, 
 and, forming a temporary organization, agreed that the 
 appropriation bills should not be passed, and no further 
 legislative business should be transacted until the speaker 
 should retrace his actions. The speaker was forced to capit- 
 ulate, a reconsideration was taken, and the Muller bill was 
 passed. The governor did not venture to refuse his signature. 2 
 
 The Muller law 3 is a general act authorizing any city in 
 
 1 There was no opportunity foj a study of this substitute bill, but it 
 was obviously intended to defeat the effective provisions of the Muller 
 bill, and probably contained clauses that would have greatly strengthened 
 the position of the companies. 
 
 1 See Atlantic Monthly, January, 1904. 
 
 * Session Laws, 1903, p. 285 (May 18).
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 245 
 
 the state to own and operate street railways under the con- 
 ditions prescribed. The act is of special significance, because, 
 in addition to the formal grant of authority, there is a care- 
 ful attempt to provide a satisfactory method for meeting 
 the serious financial difficulties involved in the policy of 
 municipal ownership, so that the grant of power may be 
 effectively used by any city which considers it advisable to 
 make use of the authority. 
 
 Before any of the powers conferred can be exercised, the 
 act must first be adopted by popular referendum in the city 
 concerned, while additional referendum votes must be taken 
 in reference to various special features of the law. The 
 authority given is " to construct, acquire, purchase, maintain, 
 and operate street railways within the corporate limits"; 
 and franchises granted before this power is acted on may 
 contain a reservation of the right on the part of the city to 
 take over the plant at some future time. Two methods are 
 authorized for securing funds for purchasing or constructing 
 municipal railways. General city bonds may be issued, 
 provided the proposition is submitted to popular vote and 
 is approved by two-thirds of those voting; but debt limits 
 are almost certain to prevent this method from being adopted. 
 The other alternative and this is the most striking feature 
 of the act is to issue railway certificates, secured by a 
 mortgage on the plant, giving the mortgagee in case of fore- 
 closure the right to maintain and operate the railway for 
 a period of not more than twenty years. Any ordinance 
 providing for such certificates must, however, be submitted 
 to popular vote and be approved by a majority of those 
 voting on the question. It was expected that such cer- 
 tificates would not be considered as part of the city debt, to 
 be included within the debt limit established by the state 
 constitution. 
 
 When a city has secured a street railway, it may operate 
 it under direct municipal management only if that policy 
 is also approved at a popular referendum by three-fifths of
 
 246 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 those voting. In lieu of this the city may lease any munici- 
 pal railway for a period of not over twenty years. But any 
 ordinance authorizing a lease to a private company for more 
 than five years must be submitted to a popular referendum 
 on the petition of 10 per cent of the voters. 
 
 In July, 1903, the twenty years' extension provided by 
 the ordinance of 1883 expired. But as no new agreement 
 had been reached at that time and the city was not yet in 
 a position to act under the Muller law, the various companies 
 remained in possession, and there was no practical change in 
 the situation. Indeed, steps had been taken in the courts 
 which prevented the city from taking any aggressive action 
 to oust the companies. On April 22, 1903, the Guaranty 
 Trust Company of New York brought suit in the United 
 States Circuit Court against the Union Traction Company 
 and other north and west side companies; and, judgment 
 being given and no property found, the roads were placed 
 in the hands of receivers. These companies had been in 
 financial difficulties for some time, as a result of the reckless 
 issue of speculative securities. But it has been alleged that 
 the suit was a collusive action for the purpose of having the 
 claims of the companies under the ninety-nine-year act 
 adjudicated in the United States courts rather than in the 
 courts of Illinois. And, at any rate, this result was secured. 
 On July 18 the receivers appointed by the court began pro- 
 ceedings before the United States Circuit Court to determine 
 the rights of the companies under the acts of 1859, 1861, 
 and 1865. 
 
 At the April election in 1904 the Miiller law was adopted 
 by the city of Chicago by a vote of 153,000 to 30,000. At the 
 same time two questions of public policy bearing on the trac- 
 tion situation were submitted, with the following result : 
 
 1. Shall the city council upon the adoption of the Miiller law pro- 
 ceed without delay to acquire the ownership of the street railways under 
 the powers conferred by the Miiller law ? 
 
 Yes, 121,957 ; no, 50,807.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 247 
 
 2. Shall the city council instead of granting any franchises proceed 
 at once under the city's police power and other existing laws to license 
 the street railway companies until municipal ownership can be secured, 
 and compel them to give satisfactory service ? 
 
 Yes, 120,863 ; no, 48,200. 
 
 It should be noted that, while both questions carried by 
 a vote of more than two to one, the vote in favor of municipal 
 ownership showed a falling off from the first vote in 1902, 
 while the vote on the other side had increased. 
 
 Meanwhile the local transportation committee has con- 
 tinued negotiations with the City Railway Company, and in 
 August, 1904, reported a tentative ordinance in regard to the 
 lines of that company on the south side of the city. Accord- 
 ing to this measure the claims of the company under the 
 ninety-nine-year act were to be commuted by allowing them 
 to continue in possession for thirteen years, after which all 
 their grants were to expire. Provisions were made for the 
 immediate reconstruction of the lines, for extensions, and 
 for improvements in service, including transfers from the 
 lines of one company to another and some through routes. 
 The city was to receive 5 per cent of the gross receipts as 
 compensation for the use of the streets, in addition to all 
 regular taxes on the property and franchises. 
 
 While this proposed ordinance was being discussed in the 
 council, Judge Grosscup, of the United States Circuit Court, 
 gave his decision in the cases concerning the north and west 
 side lines, substantially upholding the claims of the com- 
 panies that all grants made before 1875 were valid until 1958. 
 An appeal was at once taken to the United States Supreme 
 Court. But the preliminary decision made the City Rail- 
 way Company less disposed to accept the compromise in the 
 tentative ordinance. At the same time the popular agita- 
 tion in favor of municipal ownership was steadily increasing. 
 And, as a result, the winter of 1904-05 passed with no definite 
 advance toward a settlement of the situation.
 
 248 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 IV 
 
 In the municipal campaign of 1905 the street railway 
 question was even more prominent than in previous elec- 
 tions, and was, in fact, the one dominant issue. The Repub- 
 licans nominated for mayor John M. Harlan, formerly an 
 opponent of the bosses of the old party machine and a leader 
 in the council in the earlier stages of the contest with the 
 companies. At the outset of the campaign he seemed to 
 favor the adoption of the tentative ordinance, as a step 
 toward effective ultimate municipal ownership at the end of 
 the thirteen years. But before the end of the campaign he 
 had spoken more definitely in favor of earlier action. The 
 Democrats, abandoning the more conservative policy fol- 
 lowed by Mayor Harrison in harmony with the Republican 
 council, nominated for mayor Judge E. F. Dunne on a plat- 
 form calling for immediate municipal ownership and opera- 
 tion. This, it was promised, could be inaugurated by using 
 the lines where the franchises had clearly expired; and, in 
 the case of franchises which might be held valid, either by 
 condemnation proceedings or by building new lines parallel 
 to those covered by unexpired franchises. 
 
 As the outcome, Judge Dunne was elected by a majority 
 of 20,000. At the same time three more public policy votes 
 were taken, which again indicated on their face the strong 
 popular sentiment against any continuation of the franchise 
 policy. These were as follows : 
 
 1. Shall the city council pass the tentative ordinance? Yes, 64,- 
 391; no, 150,785. 
 
 2. Shall the city council pass any ordinance granting a franchise 
 to the City Railway Company? 
 
 Yes, 60,020; no, 151,974. 
 
 3. Shall the city council pass any ordinance granting a franchise to 
 any street railroad company ? 
 
 Yes, 59,013; no, 152,135. 
 
 It soon became clear that there would be little active 
 cooperation between Mayor Dunne and the city council.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 249 
 
 The council had a Republican majority; but this was not of 
 especial significance, as a number of Republican members 
 favored the mayor's policy. On the other hand, a number 
 of Democratic members were not in favor of immediate 
 municipal ownership and operation. Nevertheless, the coun- 
 cil recognized the result of the election by reorganizing the 
 local transportation committee. Alderman Foreman was 
 retired as chairman, and in his place Alderman Charles Werno 
 was selected, a Democrat and a supporter of the mayor's 
 policy. Several plans of procedure were proposed by the 
 mayor; but action on these was defeated or postponed, 
 either in the committee or in the council. 1 In the latter part 
 of the year, negotiations were again renewed with the repre- 
 sentatives of the companies; and a second tentative ordi- 
 nance was prepared and reported to the council. But this 
 ordinance did not prove satisfactory even to many of those 
 opposed to the policy of immediate municipal ownership. 
 And it was understood that leaders in the Voters' League 
 and the independent newspapers declined to support it. 
 
 1 An interesting episode was that connected with the visit of Mr. 
 Dalrymple, general manager of the municipal tramways of Glasgow, 
 Scotland. Immediately after his election Mr. Dunne cabled to the Lord 
 Provost of Glasgow, requesting the Glasgow authorities to allow their 
 tramway manager to visit Chicago. It was afterward explained that 
 Mr. Dunne had acted on the advice of Mayor Johnson of Cleveland, and 
 that the latter had in mind Mr. Young, the former manager of the Glas- 
 gow lines, who by the irony of fate had gone to London to take charge 
 of Mr. Yerkes's new undertakings there. Mr. Dalrymple came to Chi- 
 cago, saw Mayor Dunne and his friends, but was not brought into com- 
 munication with the council committee on local transportation. He 
 did, however, meet some of the representatives of the companies, and 
 looked over the situation in Chicago and other American cities. When 
 his report was received, Mayor Dunne declined to make it public on 
 the ground that Mr. Dalrymple had been his personal guest. Event- 
 ually, the council secured a copy of this report through the Glasgow 
 Town Council. The first report was brief and rather vague, recommend- 
 ing an agreement with the companies on account of the difficulties of 
 municipalization, among which were mentioned the ninety-nine-year 
 act, the methods of municipal work in the United States, and the de- 
 tached nature of the expiring franchises. A second report, sent at the 
 special request of Mayor Dunne, discussed methods of administration.
 
 250 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Under these circumstances the council decided to submit 
 to the voters at the election in April, 1906, the question of 
 authorizing an issue of $75,000,000 of street railway certifi- 
 cates, under the provisions of the Muller law, with which 
 to purchase or construct street railways; and also the ques- 
 tion of municipal operation. At the same time there was 
 submitted, under the public policy act, a general question 
 whether the city should proceed under the Muller Act in pref- 
 erence to passing franchise ordinances. The result of these 
 votes was as follows : 
 
 YES. No. 
 
 (1) On the issue of Muller law certificates . . 110,225 106,859 
 
 (2) On municipal operation 121,916 110,323 
 
 (3) Public policy question 111,955 108,087 
 
 The vote on the first question definitely authorized the 
 issue of street railway certificates under the statute. But 
 it was recognized that there was some doubt whether the 
 courts would recognize the validity of the provisions in the 
 law excluding such certificates from the city debt limit. 
 And this legal question had to be determined before active 
 measures could be taken. The vote on municipal operation, 
 although showing a larger majority in its favor, was not 
 equal to the three-fifths vote required by the Muller law; 
 and that part of the mayor's policy was, for the time at least, 
 defeated. The vote on all of the questions showed a large 
 increase over the previous referendum votes, a notable decline 
 in the vote in favor of municipalization, and an enormous 
 increase of the vote in opposition. 
 
 Just before the election the legal situation was clarified 
 by a decision of the United States Supreme Court, in effect 
 overruling the decision of the Circuit Court as to the rights 
 of the companies under the ninety-nine-year act. The Su- 
 preme Court decided against some of the arguments presented 
 for the city, denying the jurisdiction of the United States 
 courts and the constitutionality of the act of 1865. But 
 in interpreting that act the court held that, while it clearly
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 251 
 
 extended the corporate life of the older companies for a period 
 of ninety-nine years, the ambiguous clause on which the claims 
 to an extension of the franchises were based must be inter- 
 preted in accordance with the established principle " that one 
 who asserts private rights in public property under grants of 
 the character of those under consideration must, if he would 
 establish them, come prepared to show that they have been 
 conferred in plain terms, for nothing passes by the grant 
 unless it be clearly stated or necessarily implied." As Chief 
 Justice Taney had said in an earlier case, "The rule of con- 
 struction in cases of this description ... is this, that any 
 ambiguity in the terms of the grant must operate against 
 the corporation and in favor of the public, and the corpora- 
 tion can claim nothing that is not clearly given by the law." l 
 
 Applying this principle, it was held that "it cannot be 
 successfully maintained that the act of 1865 contains a clear 
 expression of legislative intention to extend the franchise of 
 these corporations to use the streets of Chicago, without refer- 
 ence to the assent of the city, for the long term of ninety-nine 
 years; and for that time preventing other and different legis- 
 lation restricting the grant of a practically exclusive right." 
 
 A dissenting opinion was filed by Justice Kenna, with 
 whom Justices Brewer and Brown concurred, upholding 
 the claims of the companies on the ground that the clause 
 clearly intended to confer such a grant, and that this inter- 
 pretation was confirmed by the opposition to the act and the 
 arguments presented in Governor Oglesby's veto message. 
 
 In discussing some minor points, the court recognized 
 the distinction in the terms of the earliest grants by the city, 
 on which the companies' rights now rested. While on the 
 north side the earlier grants had all definitely expired, on 
 
 ferine v. Chesapeake & Canal Co., 9 Howard, 172. Cf. Charles 
 River Bridge v. Warren Bridge, 11 Peters, 429; Binghamton Bridge v. 
 Binghamton Bridge Co., 3 Wallace, 51, 75; Northwestern Fertilizing Co. 
 v. Hyde Park, 97 U.S. 659; Stidell v. Grandgean, 111 U.S. 412; Corson 
 Mining Co. v. South Carolina, 144 U.S. 550; Knoxville Water Co. v. 
 Knoxville, 200 U.S. 22, 34
 
 252 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the south and west sides the franchises continued until the 
 city should purchase the plant and equipment. 1 
 
 As a result of this decision, the position of the city was 
 greatly strengthened as against the companies, which had 
 left merely a few detached pieces of street railway line, built 
 under later franchises, and on the south and west sides the 
 right to compensation for their cars and tracks. At the same 
 time the local election had committed the city to the policy 
 of municipal ownership, but had also blocked any immediate 
 municipal operation. This situation caused both the mayor 
 and the companies to modify their attitude. 
 
 On the mayor's side this change was first indicated by 
 the retirement of Mr. Clarence S. Darrow from the position 
 of special legal adviser on street railway matters, and the 
 appointment to that place of Mr. Walter L. Fisher, who had 
 been secretary and later president of the Municipal Voters' 
 League, and had drafted the original Miiller bill. This ap- 
 pointment was followed by a bitter and unwarrantable attack 
 on Mr. Fisher by some of the former opponents of the mayor's 
 policy. But it proved to be one of the wisest steps taken 
 by the mayor, and the settlement which has been adopted 
 is due in very large part to Mr. Fisher. On April 27, 1906, 
 Mayor Dunne, doubtless with the advice of his new counsel, 
 addressed a letter to Alderman Werno, chairman of the com- 
 mittee on local transportation, outlining a plan for a prompt 
 settlement, on the following basis : 
 
 (1) An agreement with the companies for the purchase 
 of their property and unexpired rights at a fixed price. 
 
 (2) The temporary continued operation of the lines by 
 the companies under a revocable license. 
 
 (3) Immediate reconstruction of the system and improve- 
 ments in the service, the cost to be repaid when the city should 
 take possession. 
 
 (4) Profits, above a fair return to the companies upon their 
 present and future investments, to be divided with the city. 
 
 1 Blair v. Chicago, 201 U.S. 400.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 
 
 253 
 
 On their part the companies accepted the general principles 
 of this plan. Negotiations were again opened between their 
 representatives and the local transportation committee, 
 with the mayor and his special counsel, Mr. Fisher, in regular 
 attendance. It is of interest, also, to note that one of the 
 prominent legal advisers in these later proceedings has been 
 John M. Harlan, who was appointed by Judge Grosscup in 
 connection with the litigation and receivership of the north 
 and west side lines, as representative of the court. 
 
 A basis for agreement having been reached, one of the 
 most important problems was to determine the value of the 
 existing plant and unexpired franchises. For this purpose 
 a special commission of engineering experts was appointed, 
 consisting of Bion J. Arnold, who had been employed by 
 the local transportation committee for several years, Morti- 
 mer E. Cooley, dean of the Department of Engineering in 
 the University of Michigan, who had directed an exhaustive 
 investigation of the physical value of the railroads of Michigan 
 a few years before, and A. B. DuPont, the mayor's engineer- 
 ing adviser. In September the companies submitted their 
 estimates, which aggregated $73,555,000. About one-third of 
 this was for franchises, on the assumption that their remain- 
 ing rights were equivalent to an average of seven years on all 
 the existing lines. But the commission's report, made in 
 December, reduced these figures by more than a third. A 
 comparative summary of the two estimates is given below: 
 
 
 PHYSICAL 
 PROPERTY 
 
 FRANCHISES 
 
 TOTAL 
 
 WITHOUT 
 
 PAVINQ 
 
 TOTAL 
 INCLUDING 
 PAVING 
 
 Chicago City Railway: 
 Company's valuation . . . . 
 Commissioners' valuation . . 
 
 $20,103,936 
 16,782,147 
 
 $10,332,228 
 3,754,363 
 
 $20,536,510 
 
 $30,436,164 
 22,369,068 
 
 Chicago Union Traction Co.: 
 Company's valuation . . . . 
 Commissioners' valuation . . 
 
 $29,294,471 
 20,853,629 
 
 $13,825,040 
 5,262,608 
 
 $26,116,237 
 
 $43,119,511 
 28,625,714 
 
 Both companies : 
 Company's valuation . . . . 
 Commissioners' valuation . . 
 
 $49,398,407 
 37,635,776 
 
 $24,157,268 
 9,016,971 
 
 $46,652,747 
 
 $73,555,675 
 50,994,782
 
 254 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The commissioners' valuation for physical property was 
 about $10,000,000 more than the valuation determined in an 
 investigation by the Arnold Company in 1902. This was 
 due in part to the increased price of materials on which the 
 estimates were based, and in part to new equipment that 
 had been added since the earlier valuation. In other respects 
 the valuation must be considered as fairly liberal to the com- 
 panies. The physical property was valued on the basis of 
 the cost of reconstruction at existing prices, less allowances 
 for depreciation. The cable roads on the south and west 
 sides were valued as operating lines (although it was evident 
 the plant must be discarded in the reconstruction work) in 
 recognition of the fact that the companies had a legal right 
 to operate these lines until purchased by the city. On the 
 other hand, the north side lines, where the city was under 
 no legal obligation to purchase at all, were estimated at the 
 value of the equipment in a reconstructed system. Whether 
 the city should repay the companies for street paving was 
 left an open question in the commissioners' report. The 
 franchise values were determined by estimating the unex- 
 pired franchises not as detached lines, but as part of the exist- 
 ing systems. And to this were added the estimated profits 
 on all the existing lines for a period of eighteen months, 
 which period, it was estimated, would elapse before the city 
 could take possession of the property by eminent domain or 
 other compulsory proceedings. 
 
 In the end the representatives of the companies agreed to 
 accept the round sum of $50,000,000 for the physical prop- 
 erty and existing franchise rights. This was practically 
 the commissioners' figures, allowing the companies the greater 
 part of their claim for street paving. A comparison of this 
 amount with the capitalization of the companies ($117,000,- 
 000 in 1901) shows to what extent the capital had been in- 
 flated on the basis of the claims under the ninety-nine-year 
 act. Indeed, three-fourths of the stock and bonds of the 
 north and west side lines have now no substantial value.
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 255 
 
 While these valuations were being determined, negotia- 
 tions proceeded on other points. Arrangements have been 
 made for the reorganization of the companies in the hands 
 of receivers and for the organization of a new company 
 the Chicago Railways Company to take over the opera- 
 tion of the north and west side lines and furnish capital for 
 the rehabilitation. The cable roads are to be reconstructed. 
 Subways are to be provided in the business district. Exten- 
 sions and new equipment are to be furnished. For this 
 purpose it is estimated that $40,000,000 will be needed. 
 It has been provided that this shall be spent under the super- 
 vision of a board of engineers, two of them designated by 
 the city. The companies, however, are to be allowed 10 
 per cent as contractor's profit, and 5 per cent brokerage over 
 the actual cost of construction, if the city should purchase 
 the plant. 
 
 Arrangements for the operation of the lines are much more 
 distinctly in the interest of the city and the public than in 
 either of the previous tentative ordinances. The companies 
 are to operate on a license revocable at any time on six months' 
 notice, the city having the right to purchase at the stipulated 
 price of $50,000,000 for the existing plant plus the cost of 
 improvements. All of the lines are to be operated as parts 
 of one system, with a considerable number of through routes 
 and transfers from one district to another. The city is to 
 have a large measure of control over the frequency of service 
 and supervision over the accounts of the company. And the 
 profits, after paying operating expenses, taxes, and 5 per 
 cent on the actual investment, are to be divided, 55 per 
 cent to the city and 45 per cent to the company. The plan, 
 as a whole, may be called one establishing a joint partnership 
 between the city and companies for the control and opera- 
 tion of the street railways. 
 
 By the middle of January, 1907, the agreement between 
 the council committee and the representatives of the com- 
 panies had been drafted in the form of proposed ordinances
 
 256 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and submitted to the council. Until the previous month it 
 had seemed probable that the arrangements would prove 
 satisfactory to all parties, and the ordinances might be passed 
 promptly. But in the latter part of December some of the 
 more radical advocates of municipal ownership raised objec- 
 tions, apparently fearing that improved service on the part 
 of the companies would satisfy the public, and that the pro- 
 visions for municipal operation would not be utilized. It is 
 true that this may be the result. But for the friends of 
 municipalization to urge this seems a confession of weakness 
 in their argument that any system of regulation is bound to 
 fail. Mayor Dunne, who had cooperated in the work of 
 drafting the ordinances, suddenly joined this late movement, 
 which took the form of demanding a popular referendum 
 on the proposed ordinances. Once this demand was made, 
 however, it should have been evident that it must be granted ; 
 and the attempt of some supporters of the agreement to oppose 
 the movement was clearly a tactical error. Petitions calling 
 for a referendum were signed by 189,000 names; and it was 
 soon acknowledged that this must be provided. 
 
 In a tense and dramatic all-night session on February 4-5, 
 1907, the ordinances came before the council for action. 
 Some minor amendments were accepted by the committee 
 and adopted. A large number of others presented by the 
 opponents were defeated. Many of these would have been 
 to the interest of the city and the public. But the represen- 
 tatives of the company had declined to accept them; and, in 
 the opinion of the majority of the council, they were not of 
 sufficient importance to cause the defeat of the agreement 
 that had been reached. Another contest arose on the pre- 
 cise form in which the referendum should be submitted. It 
 is fair to note that the opponents of the ordinance were all 
 classed among the honest, but not always among the most 
 able, members of the council, and that the few remaining 
 "gray wolves" voted with the majority. Chairman Werno 
 and a majority of the Democratic members of the council
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 257 
 
 declined to follow the mayor in his latest change of attitude, 
 and supported the ordinances. In the end the council passed 
 the ordinances by a vote of 55 to 14, subject to the result of 
 a referendum at the municipal election in April. Mayor 
 Dunne declined to sign them; but they were repassed over 
 his veto at the next session of the council. 
 
 For two months, from the passage of the ordinances by 
 the council until the municipal election, the question as to 
 their ratification or defeat was the all-important issue before 
 the people of Chicago. Around it centred the contest for 
 city officials. The Republicans, nominating for mayor F. A. 
 Busse, recently appointed postmaster of the city, strongly 
 indorsed the ordinances. The Democrats, renominating 
 Mayor Dunne, declared in favor of municipalization through 
 condemnation proceedings. But party lines were not strictly 
 followed; and notably a majority of the Democratic alder- 
 men, while supporting their party candidates, were also in 
 favor of the ordinances. Other questions, which it is not 
 necessary to consider here, also entered to some extent into 
 the campaign for city officers. In the outcome the ordinances 
 were approved by a vote of 165,846 to 132,720; while Mr. 
 Busse and most of the Republican ticket were elected by 
 much smaller pluralities. 
 
 On April 18 the Supreme Court of Illinois rendered a 
 decision in the case involving the validity of the Muller 
 law certificates, and held that these certificates must be in- 
 cluded as part of the city debt, inasmuch as they were to 
 be guaranteed by a right to operate street railways as well 
 as by the physical property of the roads. This ruling, with 
 the existing limitations on city debt, make it practically 
 impossible for the city to purchase or build a strictly mu- 
 nicipal railway without a change in the state constitution; 
 and the provisions in the new agreement for municipal pur- 
 chase will therefore be inoperative. It will be possible, 
 however, under the agreement, for the city to transfer the 
 rights to other licensee companies, on payment for the value
 
 258 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 of the property, with 20 per cent in addition, if transferred 
 to another profit-making company within twenty years. 
 
 Since the ratification of the ordinances the Chicago City 
 Railway Company has completed the agreement for the 
 south side lines. But some holders of bonds of the north and 
 west side lines declined to accept the reduced value of their 
 securities and have caused further delay in executing the 
 new arrangements in those parts of the city. The council 
 granted an extension of the time for accepting the ordinances 
 until February 1 ; and it is expected that arrangements will 
 be completed before that date. 
 
 In attempting to draw some general conclusions from this 
 contest, which rivals in duration and interest the Trojan 
 War, it is necessary to emphasize some points that are likely 
 to be overlooked, if attention is paid only to the latest stage 
 in the conflict. In the first place, the duration of the con- 
 troversy is evidence of the tenacity of purpose on the part 
 of the people of Chicago in resisting the efforts of the finan- 
 cial promoters to perpetuate their control. The public 
 policy votes on the earlier tentative ordinances showed that 
 no franchise drawn on the traditional American lines would 
 be acceptable. 
 
 In the second place, it will be a mistake to assume that 
 the adoption of these ordinances indicated that the popular 
 demand for municipalization was merely a temporary wave 
 of sentiment, which is now fast receding. The demand for 
 municipalization was indeed aroused by the intolerable ser- 
 vice and the hostile attitude of the companies, and, so long as 
 the companies maintained their former position, municipali- 
 zation seemed to be the only alternative policy. But it must 
 not be overlooked that the actual vote against the ordinances 
 was almost as large as the first vote for municipal ownership 
 in 1902, and larger than either of the subsequent votes in 
 favor of municipalization. The latest vote indicates that the
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 259 
 
 ordinances have been approved by the action of those who 
 were not willing to vote in former years for municipalization 
 but were also not willing to vote for any of the alternative 
 plans then presented. 
 
 In the third place, as stated at the outset, these ordinances 
 set a new standard in the relations between street railway 
 companies and public authorities in this country. They 
 establish on a new basis the old doctrine of public ownership 
 of the streets, and effective public control over any private 
 company which receives special privileges in the public 
 highways. The revocable license is a much more tangible 
 feature than the nominal power of revocation in Massachusetts 
 franchises, as in the Chicago ordinances there are explicit 
 means provided by which the lines can be taken from the 
 companies with whom the present agreement is made. And 
 the division of profits, supplementing the system of public 
 control, makes the city in fact an active partner in the street 
 railway business. 
 
 As to the future, the firm believers in and the convinced 
 opponents of municipalization will each have their own 
 predictions. The writer believes that there is a fair promise 
 that, if the companies carry out their part of the agreement 
 and cooperate heartily with the city authorities, there will 
 be no further steps in the direction of municipalization for 
 many years. But if the service is not brought promptly 
 to a satisfactory standard, or if there should be a revival of 
 the policy of speculative finance or political manipulation, 
 the city will not remain entirely at the mercy of the present 
 companies. In that case there may be a trial of the so- 
 called "contract plan," by which the street railways would 
 be transferred to a licensee corporation acting as trustee for 
 the city. Or it is not impossible that the state constitution 
 may be amended to provide an effective means for munici- 
 palization.
 
 260 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 BIBLIOGRAPHICAL NOTE 
 
 There is a voluminous mass of printed material on the Chicago 
 Street Railways, but it is widely scattered, and there is no complete 
 collection in one place. Among primary sources may be mentioned 
 the official records of the Illinois State legislature and the City Council 
 of Chicago, and the judicial reports on the litigated questions. The 
 most important documents have also been reprinted, and in addition 
 there have been scores of pamphlets and articles in periodicals. A 
 list of documents, pamphlets, and longer articles, excluding items hi 
 the daily and weekly press, would contain more than a hundred titles, 
 and only the more important among them are given in the following 
 list. 
 
 Official Documents : 
 
 Mayor Carter H. Harrison : Special Message, January 6, 1902, and 
 Annual Messages, May 25, 1903, April 11, 1904, and April 10, 
 1905. 
 
 Mayor Edward F. Dunne : Annual Messages, April 11, 1906, and 
 April 15, 1907. Letter to Alderman Charles Werno, April 27, 
 1906. 
 Council Committees: 
 
 Report of the Special Committee of the City Council of Chicago 
 
 on Street Railway Franchises, March, 1898. 
 Report of the Street Railway Commission, December, 1900. 
 Report of the Special Committee on Local Transportation, out- 
 lining the provisions of a renewal ordinance, December, 1901. 
 An ordinance granting rights to the Chicago City Railway Com- 
 pany (tentative ordinance), July 23, 1904. 
 Report of the Committee on Local Transportation, and ordinances, 
 
 January 15, 1907. 
 Bion J. Arnold: Reports on Engineering and Operating Features 
 
 of the Chicago Transportation Problem, 1902-1906. 
 Traction Valuation Commission : Report on the Values of the 
 Tangible and Intangible Properties of the Chicago Street Rail- 
 way Companies, December 10, 1906. 
 Judicial Reports: 
 Circuit Court of the United States : Guaranty Trust Co. v. Chicago 
 
 Union Traction Co., etc., 1903 (over 20 vols.). 
 Supreme Court of the United States : H. A. Blair et al. v. City of 
 
 Chicago, and other cases, 201 U.S. 400 (1906). 
 Supreme Court of Illinois : Lobdell et al. v. City of Chicago (1907).
 
 THE STREET RAILWAY QUESTION IN CHICAGO 261 
 
 Special Pamphlets : 
 
 History and Statistics of Chicago Street Railway Corporations 
 
 (Supplement to the Economist), 52 pp. Maps. Chicago, 1896. 
 List of Franchises, 1837-1896. Chicago, J. F. Higgins, 1896. 
 Illinois Bureau of Labor Statistics : The Street Railways of Chicago 
 
 and Other Cities (1897). 
 
 Articles in Periodicals: 
 
 Quarterly Journal of Economics, XII, 83 (J. H. Gray). 
 Municipal Affairs, V, 439-594 (Report of the Civic Federation). 
 National Conference for Good City Government, 1902 (George C. 
 
 Sikes). 
 
 Atlantic Monthly, XCIII, 109 (E. B. Smith). 
 American Law Review, XXXIX, 244. 
 Annals of the American Academy of Social and Political Science, 
 
 XX, 356; XXVII, 72; XXIX, 385. 
 International Quarterly, XII, 13 (C. S. Darrow). 
 Review of Reviews, XXXIII, 549. 
 
 Three collections of material of special value should be noted : (1) 
 that of Professor John H. Gray, of Northwestern University (the best 
 single collection), which includes the voluminous record of the Cir- 
 cuit Court proceedings, two large bound volumes of documents and 
 miscellaneous pamphlets, and a manuscript thesis by George B. Good- 
 win on "The History of the Chicago Street Railways"; (2) that of 
 the John Crerar Library, which includes a bound volume of docu- 
 ments, pamphlets, and newspaper clippings connected with the 
 Humphrey-Allen Bills of 1897, by George E. Hooker, a box of pam- 
 phlets, and also other documents separately catalogued ; and (3) that 
 of the City Club of Chicago, which includes two boxes of miscellaneous 
 documents and pamphlets. While there is some duplication each of 
 these contains important material not in the others. There are, in 
 addition, a good number of pamphlets and special reports not in any 
 of these collections.
 
 XIII 
 
 SOME CONSIDERATIONS ON MUNICIPAL OWNER- 
 SHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 1 
 
 IN the constantly accelerating public discussion on the 
 question of municipal ownership in this country, the two 
 radically opposing views have been becoming more and 
 more predominant. On one the hand is the propaganda 
 for immediate and universal municipalization, as the next 
 great step in social and political reform. On the other side 
 is the conservative or reactionary attitude that opposes any 
 movement in the direction of collectivism. These extreme 
 views are not only expressed in most of the ephemeral politi- 
 cal and newspaper debates, but are well exemplified in two 
 recent books, F. C. Howe's, The City the Hope of Democracy 
 and H. R. Meyer's, Municipal Ownership in Great Britain. 
 
 In spite of their antagonism, both of these views have this 
 in common: they assume that the question is one which 
 can be dogmatically answered either in the affirmative or the 
 negative; that the problems can be settled by a universal 
 rule expressed in a brief formula. There is also the tendency 
 on the part of the supporters of each dogma to assume that 
 the view they adopt has an ethical basis; and their views 
 are therefore expressed in the categorical imperative, with 
 little or no qualifications. 
 
 This common feature in the recent discussion is one which 
 is full of serious danger to a wise solution of the situation. 
 A careful study shows rather that there is no such simple 
 answer; that the problem contains many conflicting factors, 
 whether examined in the light of general principles or by the 
 study of detailed facts. And it is only by recognizing these 
 conflicts and difficulties that any satisfactory conclusion can 
 be reached. 
 
 1 An address delivered in Chicago (1905) and Buffalo (1906). 
 
 262
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 263 
 
 Some confusion might be expected from the vagueness of 
 the term "public utility," which is supposed to include the 
 various undertakings proposed to be brought under municipal 
 management. And in carrying out a policy of municipali- 
 zation it would become necessary to define more exactly what 
 this phrase embraces. But at the present stage of discus- 
 sion it is enough to know that it includes such enterprises as 
 waterworks, lighting plants, street railways and telephones, 
 which make use of the public streets, and for which a special 
 franchise must be granted to a private company by some 
 public authority. Practically in the United States at the 
 present time the question is one concerning lighting plants 
 and street railways. 
 
 In reference to such undertakings a brief consideration 
 will show that either complete municipalization or uncon- 
 trolled private management involves a departure from the 
 older established and generally accepted limits between 
 public and private activity. The radical socialistic and the 
 extreme individualists will each differ from this view on the 
 basis of their general principles. But on the basis of exist- 
 ing methods about which there is little complaint the under- 
 takings proposed to be municipalized involve on the one 
 hand certain public interests similar to those under govern- 
 ment management, and at the same time certain methods of 
 management identified with private business. 
 
 On the side of public interest, all of the undertakings in 
 mind agree in occupying in a special manner and practically 
 to the exclusion of others the public highways, which are 
 recognized as ordinarily exempt from private ownership by 
 the same common law which established the legal basis of 
 private ownership in other property. And this public inter- 
 est is clearly recognized by the established procedure which 
 requires a grant from the sovereign authority of the state to 
 establish the special rights of any private company in the 
 streets and roads. 
 
 In addition to this, many of these undertakings involve
 
 264 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTKATION 
 
 public interests recognized even within the "police" theory 
 of government. Street lighting, both in its historical devel- 
 opment and practical operation, is an important means of 
 maintaining order and public safety. And public control of 
 this is as logical as public control of the police force. Water 
 supply is a fundamental factor in public sanitation and fire 
 protection ; and public control for these purposes is justified, 
 on the same basis as other public administration for the 
 protection of the public health or the protection of property. 
 
 Other services affect the public interest in ways that are 
 more open to discussion; and raise questions as to the limits 
 of public action for amelioriating the condition of the poorer 
 classes, which need not be examined at this time. But from 
 what has been said, it must be clear that the public interests 
 involved are beyond question. With these public interests 
 it follows that a private company operating such services is 
 to some extent exercising a function recognized as govern- 
 mental. And if these factors were all that need be considered, 
 a prima facie case for municipal administration of such public 
 utilities would seem to have the same basis of public policy 
 as for such services as the police force, or the administration 
 of tax laws, or for the national management of the army and 
 navy. 
 
 But there are other considerations to be noted. The most 
 important is that, for a large part of each service the self- 
 interest and ability of individual consumers permit of charges 
 based on consumption without the sacrifice of essential 
 public interests. This results not only in making the conduct 
 of the services approximate closely to private commercial 
 bargain and sale, but also in giving opportunity for the 
 development of business through the peculiar ability brought 
 out almost exclusively under the stress of individual initiative 
 and private competition. . Sometimes the management of 
 the large force of employees and the complexity of the tech- 
 nical manufacturing processes subject to new inventions are 
 named as factors in emphasizing the similarity of these services
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 265 
 
 to private business; but it may be questioned whether these 
 are much, if any, more peculiar to these utilities than to some 
 clearly accepted branches of public administration, such as 
 the military and naval service. But the factors previously 
 noted are sufficient to stamp these services as analogous in 
 important respects to private business. So that municipal 
 undertakings in these respects are clearly entering the field 
 heretofore left to individual enterprise. 
 
 It is thus evident from this brief survey of the general 
 principles involved that these public utilities, as a class, have 
 a dual aspect, and that either municipal or private manage- 
 ment involves encroachment in the usually recognized domain 
 of the other. 
 
 Turning next to the specific services, it may be asked 
 whether these differ among themselves and to what extent, in 
 the relative degree of public and private interests involved ? 
 Such differences do exist; and a few points on this aspect 
 of the question may be here noted. In regard to the water 
 supply the public interests are most numerous and most 
 constant. Not only are the streets occupied and is a public 
 supply essential for fire protection, but the supply to the 
 great body of private consumers is a matter of vital interest 
 to the public health of the community; while in most large 
 cities an adequate supply can be secured only by the exercise 
 of the governmental power of eminent domain. On the 
 other hand, the private business aspects, although not lack- 
 ing, are less important than for other services. Gas and 
 electric light services clearly demonstrate the conflicting 
 forces. For street lighting, the general principle in favor 
 of public administration has the same basis as for public 
 administration of the police force. For light sold to pri- 
 vate consumers, municipal administration would seem to 
 set an example for the municipalization of every commodity 
 and service. But a dual service involves an unnecessary 
 duplication of expense in the construction of plants and 
 quipment ; and the economical advantages of a single system
 
 266 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 for both public and private lighting are too great to be per- 
 manently ignored. 
 
 In regard to street railways, the use of public streets is 
 more pronounced and significant than for the other services, 
 and if municipal ownership of the tracks without municipal 
 operation were a satisfactory permanent solution, the public 
 interests would point toward that solution as a general 
 principle. But the operation of street railways offers special 
 advantages for exceptional business management; and 
 ownership and operation by the same body seems almost 
 essential; while in most American cities the development 
 of interurban lines adds another difficulty to municipal 
 management. 
 
 The telephone service has the least claim of the utilities 
 considered to special public interests, as its use is limited to 
 a part of the population and is not so essential as any of the 
 other services. But even here, the franchise in the public 
 streets and the unmistakable advantages of a single system 
 in each city make necessary some public supervision. 
 
 Other factors vitally affecting the question are the moral 
 principles and practices of those controlling these important 
 public services. Here the most obvious and most generally 
 recognized facts are the prevalence of ignorant officials, 
 "spoils politics" and even more flagrant methods of corrup- 
 tion and dishonesty in American municipal administration. 
 There can be no question that these are most deplorable 
 evils in our municipal government and most serious obstacles 
 to any extension of municipal functions. Until the worst 
 abuses are eliminated, and political and personal favor in 
 appointments is reduced to its lowest terms, there can be no 
 successful municipal management of public utilities, or of 
 any public services. Against the grosser forms of corrup- 
 tion there seems to be a general awakening; and there is 
 some ground for hope that these may largely disappear. 
 There is also a growing public sentiment in favor of per- 
 manent expert public servants which leads to laws regulating
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 267 
 
 the civil service on the model of the national system. This 
 method is a vast improvement over the older custom of 
 rotating political favorites ; and seems to be the most practi- 
 cable way of changing our system. But it has defects in 
 operation; and there is need for a further development of 
 public opinion in regard to offices not in the "competitive 
 class," such as generally prevails successfully in regard to 
 our judges. 
 
 Opponents of municipal ownership, however, are apt to 
 assume that the dangers of corruption and the spoils system 
 are confined to public administration; and that a system 
 of private ownership entirely obviates these evils. But 
 a regime of dishonesty and low moral standards in public 
 office cannot continue long except through the connivance 
 and even the active assistance of a large part of the business 
 community. Many of the worst cases of municipal corrup- 
 tion have been in connection with the granting of special 
 franchises to private companies; and the wisest political 
 bosses find their largest gains, not in municipal works, but 
 in their "private business" enterprises. Recent disclosures 
 emphasize the danger of overpraising "business methods" 
 in contrast with political standards; but the records of our 
 judicial courts more numerous and more crowded with 
 cases, mostly civil, than those of other countries have long 
 been a standing witness to the need of some control over the 
 dealings of business men with each other, in order to secure 
 justice and fair dealing. The most serious aspect of public 
 corruption is that it threatens to destroy the machinery 
 intended to suppress the inevitable private dishonesty. So, 
 too, the "spoils system" can and does exist in full vigor in 
 the public utilities of not a few cities under private manage- 
 ment. But the argument now offered that political corrup- 
 tion is due mainly to the franchise corporations, and will 
 disappear under a regime of municipal ownership and opera- 
 tion is far too sweeping, and ignores other sources of mu- 
 nicipal mismanagement. The only remedy for these evils in
 
 268 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 both municipal and private management is the development 
 of higher standards of public morality. 
 
 Whatever light on the question may be shown by these 
 general considerations must be tested and corrected by the 
 practical results of experience. It is not possible, however, 
 to consider in detail in this paper the records of private and 
 municipal undertakings in these fields, even if the facts 
 for a thorough and unbiassed study were available. But 
 some points of criticism may be made on much of the 
 current discussion along this line on both sides of the question; 
 and a few tendencies and specific examples can be noted. 
 
 An immense amount of argument based on elaborate 
 statistical studies has been published on the successes and 
 failures of municipal undertakings as compared with those 
 in private hands. One of the gravest defects of this work, 
 so far as concerns American cities, has been the deplorable 
 system of municipal accounts, which make it impossible in 
 most cases to secure any reliable and complete data for a 
 study of municipal undertakings. Usually the bulk of the cost 
 of constructing such works (mostly for water-supply and 
 electric lighting) has been met by bonds issued on the general 
 credit of the city, and paid out of the general funds of the 
 city. The accounts for a particular undertaking usually 
 show little more than the current expenses for maintenance 
 against the annual income. Such accounts easily show 
 a large profit for the municipal undertaking. Nowadays 
 the wisest friends of municipal ownership recognize that 
 to the maintenance expenses there must be made a charge 
 for interest on the cost of construction; but there are other 
 items more elusive, which should also be included. The 
 taxes and franchise payments lost to the city as a result 
 of municipal ownership must be added; and also charges 
 on account of depreciation, which last is the most difficult 
 to make with any degree of accuracy. Some writers, ob- 
 viously interested in making a case against municipal owner- 
 ship, insist in adding also a sinking-fund charge; but if the
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 269 
 
 depreciation allowance is adequate, this is no more necessary 
 than it is for a private corporation to pay off its capital from 
 its earnings. 
 
 Accounts of large private corporations are doubtless more 
 accurately kept in most cases than those for municipal 
 finances. But this does not prove of much benefit to the 
 student of this question, since these accounts are usually 
 not accessible to any but those actively connected with the 
 management of the companies. So that on this side public 
 access to these accounts is a necessary prerequisite to any 
 thorough comparison of municipal and private management. 
 Generally, too, the accounts of private corporations do not 
 discriminate between the actual investment in the plant, and 
 the amount of securities issued as capital, while it is well 
 known that the latter is often inflated on the basis of exces- 
 sive earnings. There is, however, one test of serious private 
 mismanagement it is likely to result in a business failure. 
 And this has been known to occur even in the case of com- 
 panies operating public utilities. 
 
 Some general tendencies as to the financial results of mu- 
 nicipal and private management may, however, be noted. A 
 well-managed private company is very likely to secure more 
 efficiency in the actual work of operation than the best-man- 
 aged municipal plant. The private company is willing to 
 pay higher wages for superintendence and thus secures a 
 higher grade of ability, and in consequence a stricter control 
 over its employees and a smaller proportion of waste. At 
 the same time it may also make some saving in the individual 
 wages paid to employees, and still more in the aggregate 
 wages. 
 
 All of this should enable the private company to furnish 
 a better or a cheaper service than a municipal plant. But 
 the motive for the higher efficiency and greater economy is 
 undoubtedly the desire for larger returns to the stockholders. 
 And in so far as such larger returns are paid, the municipality 
 has a countervailing advantage in the lower rates of interest
 
 270 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 at which it borrows funds. The important and difficult 
 question to determine the net result is which of these factors 
 is the more effective in a particular instance. So far as the 
 consumer is concerned, the interest and dividends are as 
 much a part of the cost of production as the expenses of main- 
 tenance and operation. 
 
 It should be observed that this economic argument applies 
 logically not merely to the disputed public utilities, but also 
 to the accepted municipal services. If private management is 
 on the whole more effective, then it would probably be more 
 economical for a city to make a contract for a term of years 
 with a private company for its police force and fire depart- 
 ment, or even for the national government to lease the man- 
 agement of its army and navy to a syndicate of capitalists. 
 
 Another method of comparing the results of municipal 
 and private administration is by examining the services ren- 
 dered to the community. But here, too, many of the com- 
 parisons are on an inadequate basis, and the conclusions 
 are largely misleading. The prices charged for gas by the 
 municipal works in Great Britain and Germany have been 
 compared with those charged by private plants in this country, 
 without making any allowance for differences in wages or the 
 cost of raw materials. Street railway fares under the Euro- 
 pean zone system are compared with the American uniform 
 rate, municipal ownership advocates citing the lowest 
 zone rate, and the opponents emphasizing the maximum 
 distance that can be travelled for a single fare. The volume 
 of business for particular services is compared, without con- 
 sidering the effect of related services, such as gas and electric 
 lighting, or the relative development of street railway traffic 
 and the local traffic of steam railroads. 
 
 But there can be no exact comparison of such incommen- 
 surable quantities; while the differences in methods are due 
 very largely to local customs and not to the municipal or 
 private system of management. American cities usually 
 make a uniform charge for water-supply except to the largest
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 271 
 
 consumers, on much the same line as the uniform street rail- 
 way fare; while European cities measure their water-supply 
 as they do their street railway service. There would seem 
 to be some connection between the uniform rate and the 
 enormous development of both of those services in American 
 over European cities. But some writers construe similar 
 results in one case as evidence of superior private business 
 management of street railways; and in the other as proof 
 of municipal waste and mismanagement of water-supply. 
 No doubt in both cases the American method is extravagant 
 and practical only in a rich country; while it also permits 
 a wider distribution of social benefits from these public 
 utilities. 
 
 A few words may be added, summarizing what can be 
 said at present after comparing the results of municipal and 
 private management in different countries. In the United 
 States the main experience has been with waterworks. In 
 this field most of our large cities have furnished an adequate 
 supply, and the financial reports indicate that the income 
 usually is sufficient to pay not only operating expenses, but 
 interest and other charges. On the other hand, there have 
 been extravagance and corruption in connection with several 
 construction works ; some large cities have been grossly negli- 
 gent in dealing with the sanitary problems ; and in one or two 
 cases (notably Cincinnati) the revenue is clearly inadequate 
 to meet the direct charges. As to lighting plants, reference 
 may be made to the notorious failure of the Philadelphia 
 municipal gas plant; and to the equally clear success of 
 Detroit with a municipal plant for public electric lighting as 
 illustrating the absence of any uniform result. 
 
 In Great Britain and Germany there has been a much 
 greater development of municipal ownership and operation. 
 And in both countries the financial reports show that these 
 are usually operated without loss (after making due allow- 
 ances); and in some cases yield a considerable profit to the 
 relief of the tax-payers. Where changes have been made
 
 272 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 recently, it seems clear in most cases that the municipality 
 is giving better service than the private company gave in the 
 same community. But these services are very much less 
 developed than in this country under private management; 
 and the claim is made that private companies, if encouraged, 
 would surpass the municipalities. In one line, that of build- 
 ing improved dwelling houses for the poorer classes, even the 
 British cities have not succeeded in carrying on the under- 
 takings without a loss; and unless this loss can be fairly 
 charged to the account of public sanitation or charities, this 
 form of municipal ownership cannot in any way be classed 
 as a success. 
 
 No discussion of the question of municipal ownership in 
 the United States would be complete without some reference 
 to the practical difficulties and legal obstacles which stand 
 in the way of any sudden change of policy. These difficulties 
 are the existing franchises and the limitations on municipal 
 debts. 
 
 Existing franchises cannot be ignored. They must either 
 be purchased at their full value, making it more difficult for 
 a city to improve conditions than if it could start with a free 
 field; or municipal ownership must be postponed until they 
 have expired. When franchises expire at different times, 
 it is difficult to make a complete transfer at one time; and 
 it is advisable that franchises for the same purpose should 
 be granted for such periods as will cause expiration at the 
 same date. 
 
 So far as debt limits are concerned, our present system is 
 purely arbitrary, and fails to discriminate between debts for 
 different purposes. A debt incurred for a self-sustaining 
 undertaking does not impose the same burden on the property 
 owners as a debt to be paid from taxation ; and there is much 
 to be said in favor of excluding the former from the debt 
 limits. But it is not always certain whether a given under- 
 taking will be self-sustaining ; and it would be a grave danger 
 to allow cities unlimited borrowing power for undertakings
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP OF PUBLIC UTILITIES 273 
 
 which, if unsuccessful, would lay a heavy burden on the tax- 
 payers. It has therefore been suggested that loans for munici- 
 pal industries shall be secured simply by a mortgage on the 
 proposed plants ; and this was the method proposed for the 
 Chicago street railways. Such a plan seems a reasonable 
 method of allowing cities to make the experiment of munici- 
 palization. It is a limited sort of municipal ownership; 
 since if the city fails, it cannot maintain the industry at the 
 expense of the tax-payers, but must allow the mortgagees to 
 foreclose and reestablish private management. But just 
 because it is limited in this way it would compel each city 
 to prove itself capable of good management in order to main- 
 tain the municipal system. This power would simply give 
 cities the same authority now possessed by private individuals 
 to limit their liability for each undertaking by forming private 
 corporations ; and would place the city in a stronger position 
 in granting franchises. 
 
 In conclusion, no simple dogmatic doctrine can be asserted 
 now, establishing a universal policy for American cities on 
 this subject. It is a problem to be settled by each city for 
 itself, very largely on the basis of peculiar local conditions, 
 and probably with different solutions with regard to the 
 various utilities. We may expect municipal waterworks to 
 become more general than at present, and probably there 
 will be a steady increase in municipal lighting plants. But 
 no city should change to a municipal system without a care- 
 ful study of the local situation. 
 
 Since, however, it is a question whose answer depends on 
 local conditions, each city should have the legal authority 
 to determine its own policy subject to such limitations on 
 its financial powers as have been indicated. Where franchises 
 are granted to private corporations, they should be framed 
 with more regard to the public interests than has been the 
 case in most of the earlier franchises in this country. Pres- 
 ent tendencies are toward short-term franchises (twenty to 
 twenty-five years) with provisions as to rates and service;
 
 274 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 but it may be suggested that with a more continuing public 
 control over rates and service and a clear power on the part 
 of cities to purchase the plants at a fair valuation, the limita- 
 tion on the duration of the franchise is of less importance. 
 There is also a tendency to exact compensation from fran- 
 chise companies, although the revenue secured is often less 
 than under a strict system of taxation. One of the most 
 important changes that is necessary is a clear recognition of 
 the distinction between compensation and taxation; and if 
 the companies pay their full share of taxes, there is much to 
 be said in favor of securing lower charges and better service 
 rather than any additional compensation to the city for its 
 franchises. Lastly, under either public or private manage- 
 ment, there is one essential need for a complete and uniform 
 system of accounting under public control, so that the 
 actual results may become clearly known.
 
 XIV 
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 1 
 
 ANY comprehensive study of municipal government and 
 administration must be in large part based on the comparison 
 of conditions in different cities and different countries. And 
 exact comparisons covering a large number of cities almost 
 of necessity tend to be expressed in statistical form. It is, 
 however, a difficult matter to secure the desired information 
 in a sufficiently uniform scheme of classification so as to 
 make possible statistical tabulations that may be easily 
 compared. It is less than forty years since the collection 
 and publication of such data has been undertaken in any 
 country on an extensive scale. And it is less than a decade 
 since any comprehensive effort has been made in the United 
 States. Some account of the more important publications, 
 showing the development in this field, may be of interest 
 and value in calling attention to important sources of mate- 
 rial for the study of municipal problems. And some criticism 
 of what is now done may serve to bring about further im- 
 provement. 
 
 Since the establishment of the English board of poor-law 
 commissioners in 1834, financial statistics for the local English 
 poor-law authorities have been prepared. But it is only since 
 the creation of the local government board in 1871 that 
 reports from all the English local authorities have been col- 
 lated and published in the annual volume of Local Taxation 
 Returns. 
 
 These reports cover a good deal more than local taxation. 
 They give, in fact, a comprehensive survey of all the financial 
 
 1 Revised from an article published in the Quarterly Journal of Eco- 
 nomics, XIII, 343 (April, 1899). 
 
 275
 
 276 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 operations of the various local authorities, including revenues 
 of all sorts, expenditures, and loans. The English system 
 of local government, however, still presents a confusing 
 chaos of authorities which complicates the character of the 
 statements. In consequence, the statistics of municipal 
 finance cannot be found in one series of tables. Poor relief 
 and public schools form distinct series of tables, and are 
 entirely excluded from the municipal accounts; while the 
 latter are not presented as a whole, but are sharply divided 
 into borough accounts and urban sanitary district accounts. 
 The county boroughs have still another division, known as 
 the Exchequer contribution accounts. In addition there are 
 in many towns special authorities dealing with specific mu- 
 nicipal functions, burial boards, bath commissioners, library 
 trustees, market commissioners, bridge and ferry trustees, 
 joint boards, and the accounts of these are also distinctly 
 independent of the municipal accounts. 
 
 This situation makes almost impossible the presentation of 
 figures showing the total municipal receipts and expenditures 
 for particular towns; and, in fact, no attempt is made in 
 this direction. But complete details as to receipts and expen- 
 ditures for all the manifold fields of local governmental activity 
 are presented, in which the ordinary financial operations are 
 carefully distinguished from accounts dealing with loans 
 and investments of capital. The arrangement of the large 
 towns into three groups county boroughs, municipal bor- 
 oughs, and urban districts not boroughs is an important 
 step in the direction of a scientific classification; but within 
 each of these divisions the arrangement is geographical; 
 no per capita figures are given, nor are the financial statistics 
 supplemented by other information concerning the activities 
 of the various authorities. 
 
 In addition to the detailed figures for the many local au- 
 thorities, tables of aggregates for the entire kingdom are 
 appended. These show the total receipts and total expendi- 
 tures by each class of local authorities, the total receipts by
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 277 
 
 all authorities from each of the principal sources of revenue, 
 and the total outgo by all authorities for each of the impor- 
 tant departments of expenditure. These, again, are differen- 
 tiated into ordinary operations and those arising out of 
 loan transactions. 
 
 Both the French and Italian governments publish annually 
 statements of the finances of communes, and summaries of 
 these, showing totals, appear in the statistical abstracts for 
 these countries. The summary in the French Annuaire 
 Statistique gives only the aggregate receipts and expenditures 
 for all the communes in each department, with similar aggre- 
 gate figures, but no figures for any particular city, as to the 
 amount of centimes additionels and the receipts from octrois. 
 The summary in the Annuario Statistico Italiano gives only 
 aggregates for the entire kingdom; but in addition to the 
 totals of receipts and expenditures, gives itemized aggregates 
 according to a careful classification of receipts and expendi- 
 tures. Thus the total expenditures for all Italian communes 
 for general administration, for public works, for education, 
 and the like, are given. 
 
 The facts for particular Italian cities are to be found in 
 the Bilanci Comunali, published by the Ministry of Agricul- 
 ture, Industry, and Commerce. The first number appeared 
 in 1863, and with few exceptions it has been issued each 
 year since that time, though with some changes in the system 
 of classification. As now presented, there are ninety items 
 of receipts, grouped together under ten main heads, and one 
 hundred and seventy items of expenditure, grouped under 
 eight main heads. The large number of items of expendi- 
 ture is caused by the triplication of each item under each of 
 the three divisions of obligatory, facoltative, and extraordinary 
 expenditures. In accordance with this elaborate scheme, 
 the figures are given for all of the communes in each compart- 
 ment, and also for the chief town in each province. The 
 latter includes all of the considerable towns in Italy, and there 
 are thus presented for the comparative study of the munici-
 
 278 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 pal finances of these towns both detailed statistical data 
 and the totals for the main heads of receipts and expenditures. 
 
 The arrangement and grouping of the figures can, however, 
 be criticised. The towns are arranged in alphabetical order 
 by provinces, with the aggregate figures for each province 
 in alternate columns with the figures for the chief towns. 
 Thus adjacent figures in the tables are not at all those likely 
 to be compared, as would be the case were the statistics for 
 the large towns grouped in one separate series of tables, 
 having the towns arranged in the order of their population. 
 Another disadvantage is the absence of any per capita figures 
 or of any statement of municipal indebtedness. It is also 
 clear that the value of the compilation would be much in- 
 creased were it to include, in addition to finance statistics, 
 the most important facts of municipal equipment and the 
 results accomplished by the various municipal departments. 
 These would make clear how far differences in expenditure 
 in different cities were justified by the different scope of work 
 undertaken. 
 
 The question of comparative finance statistics of munici- 
 palities formed a subject of discussion at several sessions of 
 the International Congress of Statistics, as a result of which 
 it was determined in 1878 to establish an annual bulletin of 
 the finances of the largest cities of the world. The prepara- 
 tion of this was placed in charge of M. Josef Korosi, director 
 of the Statistical Bureau of Budapest; and the first Bulletin 
 Annuel des Finances des Grandes Villes, containing statistics 
 for the year 1877, appeared in 1879. The list of questions 
 for this had been sent to some fifty cities of continental 
 Europe, but complete answers were received from only four- 
 teen. The tables showed for these fourteen cities the total 
 receipts and expenditures, the detail of receipts from prin- 
 cipal sources, the detail of expenditures for the most impor- 
 tant branches of administration, as police, street cleaning, 
 education, the value of municipal property, and the extent 
 of their indebtedness. Figures were given showing both
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 279 
 
 the total amounts for each city and also per capita. The 
 cities were arranged in the tables in the order of population. 
 The bulletin containing the tables, with explanatory notes, 
 formed a pamphlet of forty pages. 
 
 Other issues of the bulletin, on the same general plan, were 
 published annually for eight years, the fifth number including 
 also synoptical tables for the quinquennial period. Twenty- 
 six cities were represented in the second issue; but there was 
 little further increase, the highest number included in any 
 one year being twenty-eight. With the exception of Wash- 
 ington, B.C., and Providence, R.I., which appeared in some 
 of the later bulletins, only cities of continental Europe were 
 represented in the tables. The British towns were inten- 
 tionally omitted on account of the important differences in 
 their administrative system from that on the Continent. 
 
 After the number published in 1889 (containing statistics 
 for the year 1884), the bulletin was discontinued on account 
 of the insurmountable difficulties in the way of securing the 
 data from a sufficient number of cities. No subsequent 
 attempt has yet been made to secure a permanent interna- 
 tional comparison of municipal statistics. More successful, 
 however, have been the comparative statistics for cities within 
 particular countries, this success being due in part to the 
 greater influence of governmental over private action, and 
 in part to the larger degree of uniformity in administrative 
 systems among the cities of each particular country. 
 
 Much the best collection of municipal statistics is presented 
 in the Statistisches Jahrbuch Deutscher Stddte. This was 
 first published in 1890, and has been continued at almost 
 yearly intervals since. It is prepared, not by the central 
 government, but through the collaboration of statistical 
 officers in the large cities, under the general editorship of 
 M. Neefe, the director of the statistical bureau of Breslau. 
 The Jahrbuch is composed of a large number of chapters, 
 each dealing with a special field of municipal activity. Thus 
 there are chapters on fire protection, street cleaning, street
 
 280 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 lighting, parks, charities, waterworks, baths, savings-banks, 
 education, libraries, taxation, and other municipal functions. 
 There are also chapters giving general information about 
 city conditions, such as those on local transportation, trade, 
 shipping, post and telegraph business, population, dwellings, 
 and even the classification of population by occupations and 
 by incomes. The first volume contained seventeen chapters; 
 but additions have been made in each number, so that, al- 
 though every subject is not treated in each number, 1 the last 
 volume has thirty different chapters. 
 
 Each chapter is prepared by one of the collaborating editors, 
 who frames the tabulation schemes and collects the informa- 
 tion from the various cities. The tables thus prepared, of 
 which there are several on each subject, contain detailed infor- 
 mation on the equipment of the various departments, of the 
 amount of work actually accomplished, and of the financial 
 conditions. Thus in the chapter on waterworks there are 
 tables giving the length of water-mains (distinguishing the 
 supply and the distributing pipes), the number of houses 
 connected and the number not connected with the water- 
 pipes, the total water-supply and its distribution for public 
 services, municipal buildings, and private undertakings. 
 Additional tables show the financial operations of the water- 
 works, the receipts from different sources, the expendi- 
 tures for administration, maintenance, additions, interest, 
 and amortization of debt, with net results, distinguishing 
 those for the complete transactions from those for ordinary 
 operation. Everywhere, too, totals are supplemented by 
 per capita and comparative figures. The other chapters 
 present no less complete and interesting information con- 
 cerning the subjects with which they deal. 
 
 1 Thus the subjects of Markets and Police have each been treated in 
 but a single number. In the case of police this is probably due to the 
 fact that in most of the larger cities the police force is not under the 
 municipal government, but is managed directly by the central govern- 
 ment.
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 281 
 
 The Statistisches Jahrbuch deals only with the cities of 
 over fifty thousand population. The earlier volumes arranged 
 the cities in order of population; but in the later numbers 
 this has been changed to an alphabetical arrangement, which 
 necessarily separates from each other the figures which are 
 most likely to be compared. The single criticism which can 
 be made on the work is the absence of any summary tables 
 of receipts and expenditure. It is, of course, true that totals 
 of this kind are based on such different conditions in the 
 various cities as to be unsafe for general comparisons; but 
 it would be of advantage to indicate the total receipts and 
 expenditures for the sake of completeness in the information 
 for each city and for use in comparing development from 
 year to year. 
 
 The Oesterreichisches Stddtebuch (prepared by the Austrian 
 Statistical Central Commission) presents just such a series of 
 summary financial tables for fifty of the largest cities in the 
 Austrian monarchy, arranging the cities in order of popula- 
 tion. These summary tables, moreover, include not only 
 statistics for the single year, but tables are given for each 
 year of the preceding decade, thus making possible a rapid 
 comparison of the development of municipal finances within 
 that period. 
 
 In all other respects, however, the Oesterreichisches Stddte- 
 buch is distinctly inferior to the Statistisches Jahrbuch Deut- 
 scher Stddte. Although the detailed figures deal only with 
 twenty-two cities compared with fifty-five in the German 
 work, it forms a much larger volume (700 pages as against 
 388); but there are no real comparisons of the various lines 
 of municipal action. In place of chapters on the various 
 municipal functions there are sections on each of the cities, 
 each section being subdivided into various divisions. If 
 the information for each city was complete, this method of 
 arrangement would make the volume of little more use than 
 a series of municipal documents for each city bound together 
 in one volume. The student of comparisons must search
 
 282 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 through the volume for the facts of interest to him, and pre- 
 pare his own tables from such figures as he may find. Further, 
 the report for each city by no means gives such complete 
 and detailed information as to all the various municipal func- 
 tions as do the chapters in the German year-book. Popu- 
 lation details (including the movement of population), educa- 
 tional statistics, figures of food consumption, and summary 
 financial statements are given for each city at length. In a 
 few cases some other matters are included, such as poor 
 relief and public lighting; but these are exceptional, and 
 there is no attempt to make the information for any city 
 cover all the undertakings of the municipality. 
 
 The Bureau of Industries under the Ontario Department 
 of Agriculture publishes annually a report on municipal 
 statistics for the Province of Ontario. This gives the statis- 
 tics of assessment and taxation (showing also per capita 
 taxation), of receipts and expenditures, and of assets and 
 liabilities. The municipalities are classified as counties, 
 townships, towns, villages, and cities; and figures are given 
 both for the separate municipalities and aggregates for each 
 class. The classification of receipts and expenditures is not 
 well adapted for comparative purposes. Several depart- 
 ments are often combined in one item, such as waterworks 
 and fire protection, a system which makes impossible a 
 comparison of either of the factors thus united. Receipts 
 from loans and payments for construction work are given 
 separately in the tables; but they are included in the single 
 set of totals for each municipality, so that it is not possible 
 to compare the total ordinary expenditure of different cities. 
 
 Despite the defects pointed out in these foreign publica- 
 tions, it must not be forgotten that in all of these cases the 
 task had been attacked with an appreciation of its impor- 
 tance before any serious efforts in this direction had been 
 made in the United States. The first attempts at any com- 
 parative statement of municipal statistics in this country 
 were in connection with the later decennial censuses. Begin-
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 283 
 
 ning in 1870, some statistics of taxation and debt were com- 
 piled; and in 1880 and 1890 the data on these points were 
 extended, and further items were collected under the head 
 of social statistics of cities. But these were not only inade- 
 quate on account of the long ten-year intervals, but were also 
 so defective in substance, classification, and arrangement as 
 to have little real value. 1 
 
 An important step in advance was taken in 1898 when 
 Congress authorized the Commissioner of Labor to collect and 
 publish annually statistics of cities of over 30,000 population. 
 At first a compilation was attempted from the printed reports 
 of various cities; but owing to the lack of uniformity in the 
 reports published, and in many cases to the lack of reports, 
 this method was soon found to be impracticable. The work 
 was then undertaken by special agents of the Department 
 of Labor in accordance with a special schedule of inquiries. 
 The results of the first investigation were published in the 
 bulletin of the Department of Labor for September, 1899; 
 and similar reports were published in each subsequent year 
 up to and including 1902. These reports furnished much 
 fuller statistical data in regard to the activities of American 
 cities and their financial operations than had been available 
 before. But the scope of the investigations was still limited, 
 while the variations in the accounting methods of different 
 cities added further difficulties in the preparation of the 
 financial statements and also made the accuracy of the 
 results in some cases open to question. 
 
 Meantime the act providing for the twelfth census had 
 authorized inquiries which covered much the same class of 
 data as that presented in the reports of the Department of 
 Labor. And after the organization of the new Executive 
 Department of Commerce and Labor, comprising among its 
 bureaus both the Census Office and the former Department 
 
 1 Cf . a criticism by Professor H. B. Gardiner, Municipal Statistics in 
 the Twelfth Census, in Publications of the American Economic Associa- 
 tion, XII.
 
 284 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 of Labor, the secretary of the new department transferred 
 the work on statistics of cities to the Bureau of the Census. 
 This bureau published in 1905 its first report on the Statis- 
 tics of Cities of over 25,000 population for the years 1902 and 
 1903. Later a similar report for the year 1903, covering cities 
 from 8000 to 25,000 population, was issued. Other reports 
 on the larger cities for the years 1904 and 1905 followed; 
 and it is expected that this will be an annual publication. 
 
 These reports of the Census Bureau have conformed in 
 their general scope to the previous reports of the Department 
 of Labor, including data on the following subjects: popula- 
 tion, area, police, fire departments, public schools, public 
 libraries, municipal water, gas and electric light plants, streets, 
 street lighting, street railways, public parks, building permits, 
 liquor saloons, food and sanitary inspection, removal of 
 garbage, almshouses and orphan asylums, marriages and 
 divorces, deaths, and public finance. But the later investiga- 
 tions have gone more into detail, and especially in the finan- 
 cial statements a new classification and schedule of items 
 has been prepared. 
 
 By means of these reports it is now possible to make statis- 
 tical comparisons of conditions in different American cities 
 such as were entirely impossible a few years ago. And the 
 facts disclosed naturally direct attention to the different 
 conditions, especially as between cities of approximately the 
 same population. This, however, is not the place to discuss 
 the results in detail. But some criticism may be offered on 
 the methods followed with a view toward the betterment 
 of the results. 
 
 One defect in the reports is the absence of any data in 
 regard to the organization of municipal government. With 
 so much variety in methods of organization as exists in this 
 country, it would be of interest to be able to find a definite 
 statement of conditions in different cities. And this infor- 
 mation could be secured with less difficulty than much of 
 what is ascertained and published.
 
 COMPARATIVE MUNICIPAL STATISTICS 285 
 
 The statistics of municipal finance have been the most 
 difficult part of these reports, owing to the utter lack of sys- 
 tem in the accounting methods of cities and the absence of 
 anything approaching uniformity. On this account the spe- 
 cial agents of the Census Bureau must in many cases go 
 over the financial accounts in detail, and sometimes go back 
 to the bills and vouchers to prepare the data. One result 
 of their work has been to draw attention to the importance 
 of uniform methods of accounting and to bring about con- 
 siderable improvements in the methods employed. But 
 until there is a nearer approach to uniformity of method, 
 there must remain some doubt as to the accuracy of the finan- 
 cial statements compiled for these reports. 1 
 
 1 Under the Uniform Accounting Law of 1902, an annual report on 
 the finances of Ohio cities is published by the Auditor of State.
 
 XV 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP IN SCOTLAND 
 
 So much has been published in the United States about 
 the municipal enterprises of Glasgow, that it may seem 
 useless to offer anything more. But it is of some service to 
 present some of the latest results of such undertakings, and 
 to correct some of the misleading statements that are made 
 about them. 
 
 It may not be generally known that Glasgow is not an 
 exceptional community in its own country in the scope of 
 its municipal activities. In fact that city has simply taken 
 the lead and carried out on a larger scale a movement that 
 is very general throughout Scotland, and is much more 
 marked than the same movement in England. 
 
 From the latest financial returns to the Scotch Local 
 Government Board (for 1903-04) it appears that 40 per 
 cent of the revenue and expenditure of local authorities in 
 Scotland is for various revenue-producing undertakings. 
 In the aggregate, more than $25,000,000 was spent for such 
 enterprises, as compared to $40,000,000 for all other purposes. 
 
 First in financial importance of these commercial under- 
 takings of the Scotch towns are the gas-works. Nearly all 
 the gas-works in Scotland are municipal. Next ranks the 
 docks and harbor works; and third, the street railways, the 
 latter being often under private companies in the smaller 
 towns. Other commercial undertakings are waterworks, elec- 
 tricity works, markets, slaughter-houses, and in Glasgow 
 alone there has been a municipal telephone system. 
 
 According to the financial reports, all of the above-named 
 
 287
 
 288 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 undertakings seem to be conducted on sound commercial 
 principles. The revenue is more than sufficient to meet 
 working expenses and all debt charges. For the year 
 1903-04, the aggregate surplus revenue was about $425,000. 
 Besides the strictly commercial enterprises, the Scotch 
 towns carry on other revenue undertakings, where a con- 
 siderable loss is expected in view of the public benefits 
 derived. Such are the public baths and wash-houses, work- 
 ing-class dwellings, built in connection with street and 
 sanitary improvements, and burial-grounds. These have 
 been undertaken largely in the interest of the public health; 
 and even critics of some of the more recent commercial 
 undertakings do not find fault with the deficit of $500,000 
 (for 1903-04) in these sanitary enterprises. 
 
 THE GLASGOW TRAMWAYS AND TELEPHONES 
 
 Doubtless the most important single municipal under- 
 taking in Scotland is the Glasgow tramways, which have 
 already attracted so much attention in America. The lines 
 are being steadily extended into districts beyond the city 
 limits, and the traffic continues to increase, while the finan- 
 cial results are highly favorable. 
 
 At the end of the last fiscal year (May 31, 1906) there 
 were 160 miles of car lines in operation, nearly three times 
 the amount in the first year of municipal operation (1894-5). 
 The traffic during 1905-06 was 208,000,000 passengers, 
 almost four times as many as in 1894-5. And the average 
 fare paid was slightly under a penny, or two cents. 
 
 The number of passengers carried is, however, less than 
 in American cities of the same size. And in comparing fares 
 it is necessary to remember that the distances travelled are 
 on the average much less than in America. But it must 
 also be kept in mind that the longer distance traffic is taken 
 care of very largely by the local train service of the steam 
 railroad companies at exceedingly low fares. The two 
 largest railroad companies have each underground lines
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 289 
 
 across the city; and each of the three railroad companies 
 have a number of circular loops around the outlying districts 
 with frequent trains. Within most of the suburban residence 
 district weekly tickets are sold, good for any number of rides 
 in either direction, at one shilling and sixpence, or thirty- 
 six cents. And while the tramways are steadily cutting 
 into this railroad traffic, a huge volume of business is still 
 done in this way, for which it is impossible to secure accurate 
 statistics. 
 
 In examining the financial results, it is important to em- 
 phasize two items of expenditure. The Glasgow tramways 
 department lays and keeps up the street pavement between 
 its tracks; and it is noteworthy that this part of the pave- 
 ment is frequently better than that maintained by the high- 
 ways committee. And the tramways department also pays 
 regularly taxes to the various local authorities in whose 
 territories there are tracks. In 1905-06 the total taxes paid 
 amounted to $210,000, which was rather more than 5 per 
 cent of the total income. Some recent American franchises 
 have provided for a payment to the city of 5 per cent of the 
 revenue in lieu of taxes and ostensibly also as a payment for 
 the franchise. It is significant that the Glasgow tramway 
 pays as much simply as taxes in the ordinary way. 
 
 After paying these items in addition to the ordinary 
 working expenditure, interest, sinking-fund and depreciation 
 charges, the Glasgow tramways yield a net surplus which 
 enables an annual payment of considerable amount into 
 the fund known as the Common Good. For several years 
 this annual payment has been $125,000. In 1906 it was 
 $175,000. And the total amount paid in since 1894 has 
 been $950,000. 
 
 It is also worth noting that the debt incurred for the 
 Glasgow tramways is practically secured only by the under- 
 taking itself. From the first loan made to build the tracks 
 in 1872, the acts authorizing the city to borrow money for 
 tramway purposes have made no provision authorizing a tax
 
 290 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 to be levied to meet any possible deficit in the revenue. 
 Interest and principal on these loans must be paid from the 
 tramways revenue, or if that fails, from the private funds 
 of the city in the Common Good. This arrangement is some- 
 what similar to that proposed for municipal street railways 
 in Chicago, and might well be adopted by any other American 
 city which may undertake to establish a municipal system. 
 
 Whatever may be thought of the value of Glasgow's ex- 
 perience for American cities, it seems clear that the Glasgow 
 tramways are an undoubted success for that city. And there 
 is no substantial foundation for recent attempts to minimize 
 the extent of that success. 
 
 For five years the city of Glasgow operated a municipal 
 telephone system, which a year ago was turned over to 
 the national Post-office Department. This experiment was 
 hailed for a time as the beginning of a new branch of mu- 
 nicipal ownership. And its abandonment will doubtless be 
 as strongly urged as a complete failure. It should therefore 
 be worth while to examine just what has been accomplished, 
 and why the undertaking has been given up by the city. 
 
 The municipal system was established on account of the 
 inadequate service and the high rates charged by the National 
 Telephone Company, which supplied Glasgow in connection 
 with its system of local and long-distance services throughout 
 Great Britain. In 1893 the city first applied for authority 
 to construct and operate a competing system, but it was 
 not until 1901 that it was given the necessary powers and 
 the municipal plant was inaugurated. Since then the two 
 systems have been in active competition. The municipal 
 plant offered the lowest rate for unlimited service, $25 a 
 year. But the National Telephone Company introduced 
 multiple party lines at low rates, and had also the decided 
 advantage of its long-distance connections to other cities. 
 
 Under these conditions, while the municipal system was 
 developed far beyond the original plan, its service remained 
 smaller than the older system, and financially was conducted
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 291 
 
 at some loss. On the face of the reports there remained a 
 small surplus of revenue over expenditure; but the depre- 
 ciation allowance was insufficient, and in the last year sank 
 to the insignificant sum of $240 on a capital investment of 
 $1,800,000. 
 
 These results confirm the experience of American cities as 
 to the inadequacy of competition in the telephone business ; 
 and also show the weakness of a purely local service as com- 
 pared with a national system. It is possible that the mu- 
 nicipal system would have shown better results in the future, 
 if the city had been permitted to purchase the local plant 
 of the National Telephone Company, when its license ex- 
 pires in 1911, and if the long-distance lines were then to be 
 taken over by the Post Office as part of the telegraph system. 
 But the Post-office Department decided to take over both the 
 local and long-distance services of the National Telephone 
 Company, and to refuse any new licenses for municipal 
 plants. 
 
 In these circumstances the city of Glasgow had practically 
 no alternative but to dispose of its plant to the national 
 government, which could then furnish a more complete ser- 
 vice than either of the existing systems. Accordingly ar- 
 rangements were completed for the sale of the municipal 
 plant to the Post-office Department for $1,500,000. After 
 deducting the amount of loans repaid, and the depreciation 
 and sinking-funds from the total capital investment, this 
 involves a net loss to the municipal treasury of $75,000. 
 
 Against this loss there may be considered the advantages 
 to the telephone users from the cheaper and better service 
 secured, as the result of the establishment of the municipal 
 service. There is no method of calculating what this amounts 
 to. And there will, of course, be wide differences of opinion 
 as to the justice of placing this amount on the overburdened 
 tax-payers. At least the city was fully justified in giving up 
 the experiment. And in so doing the Glasgow Town Council 
 has shown its sober sense in adhering to commercial prin-
 
 292 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 ciples rather than following a vague theory of municipalizing 
 everything. 
 
 BIRMINGHAM ENTERPRISES 
 
 Thirty years ago, under the influence of Joseph Chamber- 
 lain, Birmingham took a leading part in the movement for 
 the material betterment of municipal conditions and the 
 extension of municipal activities, which became general 
 among the large British cities. Large street-improvement 
 schemes were carried out, and in connection with these, the 
 city became the owner of important estates and building 
 property. A water-supply was constructed. And the city 
 purchased and operated the local gas-works. 
 
 Following the decade in which this aggressive policy was 
 pursued, there came a period of comparative quiescence. 
 The works and institutions established were maintained; 
 but no new lines of activity of any importance were under- 
 taken. And the municipal authorities may be said to have 
 rested on their oars, while other cities have taken the lead. 
 
 Within the past few years, however, Birmingham has again 
 become aroused; and another period of unusual activity 
 seems to have opened. A new water-supply, one of the 
 largest in the kingdom, has been built. The street railways 
 are being taken over by the city. And for the improvement 
 of housing conditions a somewhat novel policy has just been 
 inaugurated. 
 
 Before noting these new undertakings, some attention may 
 be given to the municipal gas-works. These are the most 
 successful of the earlier series of municipal establishments, 
 and perhaps the most successful of municipal gas-works in 
 Great Britain. The works were purchased in 1875 at a cost 
 of $10,000,000. This sum included a considerable allowance 
 for good-will or the established business, in addition to the 
 value of the physical plant. Prices were reduced to some 
 degree, but were not made as low as in Glasgow, for several 
 years prices were from 65 to 80 cents per thousand feet.
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 293 
 
 The income from the beginning yielded a considerable sur- 
 plus profit, after paying all expenses for operation, interest, 
 and sinking-fund charges, and even extensions. 
 
 During the thirty years since municipal operation was 
 begun, the prices have been still further reduced, the con- 
 sumption of gas has increased steadily, and a surplus profit 
 has been regularly realized. Prices now range from 42 to 
 60 cents per thousand, averaging 50 cents. The surplus of 
 the past ten years has averaged $190,000 a year. In thirty 
 years the total surplus has amounted to $5,500,000. And 
 while the gas consumption has almost trebled, the expenditure 
 charged to capital account has increased only 25 per cent. 
 This contrasts sharply with the inflation of capital in pro- 
 portion to gas consumption in the United States. In part 
 the result in Birmingham has been due to the policy of making 
 extensions out of earnings, so that the real profit has been 
 much greater than the surplus shown on the books. 
 
 The new water-supply inaugurated in July, 1904, is from 
 the Elan valley in Wales, eighty miles from Birmingham. 
 The watershed covers an area of over seventy square miles. 
 The plans provide for six reservoirs, four of which are com- 
 pleted or under construction. These will be sufficient to 
 furnish in a dry year a supply of 75 million gallons a day 
 for two hundred days. Sand filter beds have also been built, 
 both in the Elan valley and at the service reservoirs near 
 Birmingham. The works in the Elan valley were built by 
 direct labor, while the aqueduct was constructed under 
 contract. 
 
 With the completion of the works now under construction, 
 the new supply will cost rather less than $30,000,000; while 
 an additional outlay will be necessary for the remaining 
 reservoirs when they are required. As the new supply is far 
 in excess of the present needs of the city, the water-rents 
 and other revenue do not meet all of the charges connected 
 with the loan for the new works. Up to 1899 the Birming- 
 ham waterworks had shown a net surplus profit of $850,000.
 
 294 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTEATION 
 
 But for the past seven years there has been a balance on the 
 loss side; and the net loss at the present time amounts to 
 $1,850,000. With the increased use of the new supply, this 
 loss should be gradually reduced. 
 
 Street railway conditions in Birmingham are in a transi- 
 tion stage. The first lines were built by private companies. 
 Later the city took over the tracks and built extensions, 
 but leased the lines and did not attempt operation. About 
 three years ago, however, municipal operation was begun on 
 one line; and this policy will be extended as fast as existing 
 leases expire. Meanwhile the service is distinctly inferior 
 not only to that in Glasgow, but also to that in other English 
 towns, such as Manchester and Liverpool, where the lines are 
 run by the municipal corporations. 
 
 As in other British cities, one of the most serious problems 
 now facing the municipal authorities is the housing conditions 
 of the working-classes. And in this field a somewhat novel 
 policy has just been promulgated. 
 
 In connection with street-improvement schemes of three 
 decades ago, the city of Birmingham became the owner of 
 considerable real estate, on which improved dwellings for 
 the working-classes were built. And more recently addi- 
 tional houses have been constructed under later acts of 
 Parliament. But these undertakings generally show a finan- 
 cial loss, which has been accepted, however, as part of the 
 cost of the sanitary and street improvements. 
 
 Nevertheless, there has been a strong opposition to any 
 further extension of the house-building policy. And the 
 later work of the city government has been directed toward 
 compelling the private owners to improve their property 
 so as to remove the worst of the unwholesome conditions. 
 A good deal has been accomplished by opening up houses 
 in rear courtyards to the street; while the regulations for 
 new buildings prevent the construction of more buildings 
 of the worst kind. 
 
 But the need for further action in reference to building
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 295 
 
 in new sections has been felt. And in 1905 a committee 
 visited a number of German cities; and as a result of their 
 investigations the new policy has been proposed. This policy 
 is to have the city purchase suburban real estate, to be leased 
 or sold in small lots for building purposes, after reserving 
 tracts for public buildings and open spaces. It is believed 
 that this will reduce the speculation in suburban real estate, 
 without involving the city in the risks of building operations 
 or managing the buildings that may be constructed. 
 
 The suggestion for this plan came from the investigation 
 of conditions in the city of Ulm, in Bavaria, where the munici- 
 pality owns four-fifths of the real estate within the city limits. 
 It also resembles the plan undertaken by the city of Milan ; 
 Italy. 1 To apply it in Birmingham will, however, require 
 additional legislation from Parliament. 
 
 This new housing policy was, however, threatened by an 
 unfortunate intrusion of national politics into municipal 
 elections. Birmingham has long been known as the English 
 city where the party system has been most thoroughly applied 
 in municipal contests. And for many years the Unionists 
 have controlled the council by a large majority. But there 
 are a few seats held by Liberals; and a few years ago the 
 Unionists permitted the election of a strong Gladstonian 
 Liberal, who was recognized as the best man to take charge 
 of the educational administration turned over to the council 
 by the Act of 1902. 
 
 At the municipal election in November, 1906, the term of 
 the chairman of the housing committee expired. This gentle- 
 man, Mr. Nettlefold, had been elected for many years as a 
 Unionist ; and is indeed related by marriage to Joseph Cham- 
 berlain. But at the last parliamentary election he was unable 
 to follow the Unionists in their tariff policy. And on this 
 account the Unionists selected a candidate to contest his 
 reelection. 
 
 Mr. Nettlefold, however, was supported by many Unionists 
 
 1 See p. 344.
 
 296 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 who believed that his views on the tariff had no bearing on 
 his qualifications as a municipal councillor, and who believed 
 in particular that his retention in the council was essential 
 for carrying out the new housing policy. Prominent among 
 these was Professor W. J. Ashley, formerly of Harvard Uni- 
 versity, who has been one of the leading supporters of Mr. 
 Chamberlain's tariff policy. The result of the contest was 
 the reelection of Mr. Nettlefold, and the defeat of those who 
 wished to increase the influence of the national party organi- 
 zations in the local contests. 
 
 SOME MUNICIPAL PROBLEMS IN LONDON 
 
 Any study of municipal conditions in the metropolitan 
 community of England is greatly complicated by the con- 
 fusing list of local authorities with overlapping areas and 
 jurisdiction, and the absence of any central organization for 
 the whole community with comprehensive powers in local 
 affairs. Some questions are entirely in the hands of the 
 direct agents of the central government; while the local 
 authorities include the county council, the ancient city cor- 
 poration, twenty-eight metropolitan boroughs, thirty boards 
 of poor-law guardians, and a number of other special boards 
 and commissions. No attempt will be made here to describe 
 the organization, functions, and interrelations of these various 
 authorities. But this paper will deal only with conditions 
 affecting the two important services of local transportation 
 and lighting. 
 
 Local transportation conditions illustrate in a striking 
 manner the lack of system or even any serious attempt at 
 orderly control that pervades the whole chaos of local affairs 
 in London. There are four principal means of local transit, 
 the local service of the trunk railroads, the underground 
 railroads, the surface tramways, and the omnibuses. All 
 of these are operated by private corporations, except the 
 tramways, most of which 'are now under the management 
 of the County Council. Besides these the 11,000 licensed
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 297 
 
 hackney cabs and carriages carry a good many million pas- 
 sengers in the course of a year, and form an appreciable 
 factor in the surface traffic on the public streets. 1 
 
 Regular omnibus lines in London date from the early 
 years of the nineteenth century, and in spite of the modern 
 developments they still carry a large fraction of the local 
 passenger movement. There are now some 3600 licensed 
 busses, operated by a number of companies, and no complete 
 record of their traffic is available. The two principal com- 
 panies have about 2000 busses, and carried, in 1905, 288,000,- 
 000 passengers. From this it may be roughly estimated 
 that approximately 500,000,000 passengers are annually car- 
 ried on all the bus lines in the metropolitan district. Until 
 two or three years ago, horse-power was still the uniform 
 motive power. But gasoline motor busses have been rapidly 
 coming into use; and in spite of their noise and other dis- 
 agreeable features, their greater speed and larger carrying 
 capacity give them a distinct advantage, so that their use 
 seems likely to increase. And omnibuses of some sort are 
 inevitable so long as tramway tracks are not allowed on the 
 surface of the streets in the limits of the "city" corporation. 
 But at best the bus service is slow, and for long distances 
 expensive. On a few short lines run by the County Council, 
 there is a halfpenny fare. In general the lowest rate is one 
 penny, or two cents; and this increases with the distance to 
 as high as ninepence for some of the longest runs by motor 
 busses. The busses are used mostly for short distances, 
 and the average fare paid is about one and a half pence. 
 
 Tramways, or surface street railways, were not established 
 in London until long after their introduction in other British 
 cities; and they are still of less relative importance than in 
 other British or European cities. The lines were mainly 
 begun by private companies, under agreements with various 
 
 1 An actual count of wheeled traffic at various points showed that at 
 the two busiest corners (Mansion House and Marble Arch) more than 
 22,000 vehicles passed in one day from 8 A.M. to 8 P.M.
 
 298 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 local authorities. In 1895, the County Council began the 
 purchase of lines which were at first leased; but in a few 
 years the policy of municipal operation was begun, and since 
 April, 1906, most of the tramways within the county of London 
 are owned and operated by the County Council. A number 
 of lines in the metropolitan district, but outside of the county 
 of London, are owned and operated by other local authorities, 
 as in Croydon and East Ham. And there are also a number 
 of small private companies, and oiie company of considerable 
 importance, operating lines both within and without the 
 county. Thus even this factor in the methods of transpor- 
 tation is not yet organized into a comprehensive system. 
 
 Much the most important part of the tramway net is that 
 under the control of the County Council. This includes over 
 100 miles of track, nearly half of the whole track mileage in 
 the metropolitan district, and carried, in 1905, 300,000,000 
 passengers, or two-thirds of the total number of passengers 
 (433,000,000) in the metropolitan district. Fares on the 
 County Council lines range from a halfpenny to threepence, 
 more than four-fifths of the passengers paying a penny or 
 less, and the average fare is slightly less than one penny. On 
 most of the other lines, both private and municipal, the aver- 
 age fare is something more than a penny ; but in the municipal 
 lines of East Ham, the average fare is .64 of a penny. The 
 low averages are due largely to the comparatively short dis- 
 tances travelled; and the difference between the County 
 Council and other lines may be ascribed in part, at least, to 
 the advantages of the larger mileage under the control of 
 the former. At the same time the County Council can claim 
 the advantages of a better service and of halfpenny fares for 
 very short distances. 
 
 The greatest defects in the London tramway service are due 
 to the absence of through lines across the central district 
 and the lack of a unified management. The former difficulty 
 can only be remedied by extensive and expensive street 
 widenings. The latter can now be most easily accomplished
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 299 
 
 by extending the jurisdiction of the County Council ; but it 
 seems doubtful whether this can be attained at present. It 
 should also be borne in mind that the possibilities of street 
 railway development are limited by the other means of local 
 transportation. 
 
 Underground local railways were constructed and operated 
 in London long before they appeared in other large cities; 
 and with their recent development they form one of the three 
 leading factors in local transportation. The early lines were 
 built well below the street surface, and were operated by 
 steam engines ; and in spite of the darkness, smoke, and other 
 disagreeable features were well patronized. Within the 
 last half-dozen years a new series of underground electric 
 lines have been constructed in subways comparatively near 
 the surface; while the lines of the old metropolitan and dis- 
 trict roads have also been electrified. All together there are 
 now 130 miles of local railroads in the metropolitan district, 
 with 125 stations, representing a capital of $350,000,000 and 
 carrying 300,000,000 passengers a year. 
 
 Rates of fare on the older lines vary according to distance, 
 and also for the different classes of carriages. The great 
 bulk of the passengers travel third class, and the average 
 fare paid is under one and a half pence. On the newer lines 
 the uniform fare has been introduced, and is regularly fixed 
 at twopence. These rates for the long-distance local traffic 
 is distinctly lower than the standard five-cent fare in Ameri- 
 can cities. But it must be borne in mind that the multi- 
 plicity of companies and lines prevents anything like a com- 
 prehensive system of transfers; and many passengers must 
 regularly pay two fares for each journey. 
 
 There remains the local service of the trunk railroads. 
 The ten principal railroad companies entering London have 
 all together 500 miles of passenger tracks and 386 passenger 
 stations in the metropolitan district. On these, local trains 
 are in constant operation at special rates far below the par- 
 liamentary rate of a penny a mile on the through trains;
 
 300 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and a traffic which must aggregate several hundreds of mill- 
 ions of passengers is carried. But no separate record is 
 kept of the local London traffic of these trunk lines ; and only 
 the roughest estimate can be made of its amount. 
 
 If all the available data be combined, with estimates for 
 the unknown items, the total local passenger traffic in the 
 London metropolitan district is indicated to be in the neigh- 
 borhood of 1,500,000,000 a year, or over 200 journeys per 
 head. The various means of transportation thus accommo- 
 date to a vast extent the pressing demand, and on the whole 
 at rates of fare that seem low compared with American stand- 
 ards. Yet it must be admitted that conditions are far from 
 satisfactory; and there seems to be clear need for some more 
 comprehensive control over the whole question. Neither 
 public nor company management has reached the stage of 
 consolidating even all the different routes of one method of 
 transportation; and it does not seem possible that this can 
 be done for all the different methods. Probably municipal 
 tramways and companies for the bus lines and underground 
 railways will be the prevailing methods. But there seems 
 a clear need for some public authority having jurisdiction 
 over the whole metropolitan area, with power to regulate 
 the future development of new routes and to bring the differ- 
 ent methods of transportation into closer interrelations with 
 each other. 
 
 The works for the supply of electricity to London also 
 illustrate the dual methods of municipal and company man- 
 agement. Sixteen of the twenty-nine metropolitan boroughs 
 and cities have power to retail electricity, and all but two 
 of these operate generating plants. At the same time there 
 are no less than thirteen electric companies operating in the 
 administrative county. To some extent these different au- 
 thorities overlap. In two boroughs the municipal plant is 
 in competition with a company plant; and in ten boroughs 
 there are two or more companies in competition. Roughly 
 speaking, the northern and western districts are supplied
 
 MUNICIPAL ACTIVITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN 301 
 
 by municipal plants, and the central and southern sections 
 by companies. On the basis of population, the municipal 
 plants serve the larger share of the community; but the 
 companies have the central districts including the cities 
 of London and Westminster and the borough of Holborn 
 where the greatest demand exists ; and in fact the companies 
 supply about three-fourths of the total electrical energy. 
 
 There are two main methods of charging for current, 
 the flat rate and the maximum-demand rate. But under 
 either method there are variable rates, according to the time 
 or the amount consumed, which make difficult a comparison 
 of rates from different plants. For the companies there are 
 maximum rates fixed by Parliament, subject to reduction 
 by the board of trade at intervals of seven years; but in 
 fact none of the companies charge the maximum rate. The 
 average price received for current to private parties from 
 municipal plants in 1904 was three and a fourth pence per 
 unit, and from company plants a little over fourpence; but 
 for public lighting the average price from the companies 
 was a little under the cost in municipal plants. 
 
 Comparing the financial accounts of the various plants, 
 the working expenses of the municipal and company plants, 
 on the average, are the same per unit of current, but two of 
 the municipal plants show a very high working expenditure, 
 of double this average. In the payments to capital for in- 
 terest and dividends the municipal plants show a distinct 
 saving ; and as a whole their surplus is as large in proportion 
 to output as the companies. But three of the municipal 
 plants show a deficit, and in one other case the surplus 
 is a negligible factor, two of these four being the plants 
 where the operating expenses are unusually high. 
 
 As the net result, it may be said that in most cases the 
 municipal plants show a fair degree of success, selling cur- 
 rent at a lower rate than private plants, and operating the 
 plants at a financial profit. But in some cases the financial 
 results are not successful. On the other hand, the higher
 
 302 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 rates and excessive dividends of some of the companies indi- 
 cate that neither competition nor public control has been 
 adequate. Moreover, the multiplicity of plants prevents the 
 development of the most economical results; while the two 
 opposing methods of management hinder the establishment 
 of a consolidated system. The County Council has proposed 
 to establish a central generating system; but this extension 
 of municipal activities has been vigorously opposed by the 
 companies, and one result of the defeat of the Progressists 
 at the election in March, 1907, will be at least the postpone- 
 ment of any steps in this direction. 1 
 
 1 STATISTICS OP ELECTRICITY PLANTS IN LONDON, 1904-05 
 
 BOBOUGH COUNCILS COMPANIES 
 
 Capital 4,713,106 12,257,449 
 
 Revenue 433,562 1,682,627 
 
 Working Expenses 231,235 755,002 
 
 Interest and Dividends 136,751 737,659 
 
 Surplus 96,949 227,627 
 
 Average Price 
 
 Private Supply 3.25<J. 4.06d. 
 
 Public Supply 2.06dL 1.99<f.
 
 XVI 
 
 LOCAL TRANSPORTATION IN BERLIN 
 
 As in the other metropolitan cities of Europe and America, 
 so in Berlin there is a complicated variety in the means of 
 local transportation. The largest traffic is that carried by 
 the surface street railways. But omnibuses still do a con- 
 siderable share of the passenger movement, and the local 
 steam railway service is of rather more importance. And 
 there is also a combination elevated and underground road; 
 while the cab service is also a factor in the situation. 
 
 These various methods of transportation also illustrate 
 different methods of ownership and management. But for 
 the most part the services are operated by private companies. 
 The street railway lines are conducted in accordance with 
 carefully drawn franchises; and an examination of these is 
 of special value as illustrating what can be accomplished 
 under the franchise policy in the hands of a competent and 
 honest municipal government. 
 
 It is necessary, however, to an understanding of the trans- 
 portation situation, to keep in mind that the urban community 
 to be served includes a good deal more than that within the 
 city limits of Berlin. The population within the city limits 
 in February, 1906, was 2,040,222. But including the adjacent 
 suburbs, among which are the important cities of Charlotten- 
 berg, Schoneberg, and Rixdorf, there is a total population 
 of 2,993,470. The transportation services must be studied 
 with reference to the whole of this larger community ; although 
 the problem is complicated by the absence of any consoli- 
 dated local authority. 
 
 Street railways were not introduced into Berlin until 1866. 
 
 303
 
 304 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 For the first year the traffic was less than a million passen- 
 gers, and by 1873 had increased to only three millions. But 
 in the next three years the traffic jumped to twenty-six mill- 
 ions, double the omnibus traffic, and since then has increased 
 steadily and rapidly. In the late nineties the lines were elec- 
 trified ; and the street railway traffic in 1905 was 454,000,000, 
 about two-thirds of the total local movement of passengers. 
 
 There are still a number of different street railway com- 
 panies in Berlin. Much the most important is the Grosser 
 Berliner Strasseribahn Gesellschaft, which operates the lines 
 of three other companies, as well as its own. The existing 
 contract between this company and the city was made in 
 1897, when new arrangements were made to secure the use 
 of electric power. 
 
 This contract extended the rights of the company from 
 1911 to 1919. But after securing the grant from the city, 
 the company obtained from the railway department in the 
 Prussian government, under a new local Railways Act, cer- 
 tain grants and privileges until 1949. This complicates the 
 situation, and makes it in some degree similar to that in 
 Chicago before the decision of the Supreme Court in April 
 of last year. And at the expiration of the local franchise 
 in 1919 there will probably be litigation to determine the 
 exact status of the company. 
 
 It is said that the grant from the state was largely a matter 
 of personal favor, as the head of the company is an ex-minister. 
 Such a charge is a serious criticism on the boasted integrity 
 of the Prussian administration. While at best the situation 
 shows a spirit of interference by the central government in 
 local matters, such as has been one of the great difficulties 
 in American municipal affairs. 
 
 The contract with the city is a document of over thirty 
 printed pages, covering many details in regard to the con- 
 struction and electrical equipment and the operation of the 
 lines. But the most important items are those about the 
 rates of fare and payments to the city.
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 305 
 
 Within the city limits and on lines extending to a number 
 of the suburbs, a uniform fare of two and a half cents is estab- 
 lished. This is a little higher than the lowest fares for short 
 distances in Glasgow and some of the other British cities. 
 But considering distances, it probably is the lowest street 
 railway fare in the world. And the effect is seen in the great 
 development of traffic, which is much larger in Berlin (in 
 proportion to population) than in any other European city. 
 
 "For the use of municipal property" (that is, the streets), 
 the company pays the city eight per cent of the gross income 
 from the lines in Berlin. In addition it is provided that when 
 the net income on the capital stock of 1897 exceeds twelve 
 per cent (and on additional stock over six per cent) half of 
 the surplus will go to the city. 
 
 These provisions are in addition to other payments, at 
 rates fixed in the contract, for street paving. And they are 
 also entirely independent of the regular state and local taxes, 
 which are levied on the land and buildings of the company, 
 and on the personal incomes of the stockholders. But there 
 are no special franchise taxes, such as are now levied in some 
 American states. 
 
 Under these provisions the city receives a very considerable 
 amount of revenue in fact, a good deal more than any 
 other city receives either from private companies or in the 
 way of profits from a municipal system. In 1905 the com- 
 pany paid more than $600,000 as the eight per cent of its 
 gross income ; and in addition, since 1903, it has paid a share 
 of its surplus earnings, as prescribed in the agreement with 
 the city. 
 
 Besides the lines operated by this company there are several 
 other small companies, while three lines of street railway are 
 owned by the city, but operated by the Siemens and Halske 
 Company. But the total passenger movement on these is 
 comparatively small. Of somewhat more importance is the 
 combined elevated and underground electric road, which 
 makes a partial circuit of the city, but does not reach the
 
 306 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 business district. From these lines additional small amounts 
 are paid to the city treasury. 
 
 In regard to the quality of the street railway service, it 
 cannot be called more than moderately good. The cars are 
 of fair size, but are not kept as clean as they might be. And 
 perhaps owing to the congestion of traffic, the cars move 
 very slowly in the central districts of the city. A subway 
 under some of the principal streets is much needed, and 
 would improve the situation a great deal. 
 
 Next in importance to the street railways is the local steam 
 railway service, which is part of the Prussian system of state 
 railways. In 1882 the government opened for service an 
 elevated steam railway running east and west through the 
 heart of the city. This Stadibahn is used both for through 
 and local trains. Two tracks are reserved for through trains 
 from the east and west, which stop at five of the more impor- 
 tant stations. Two other tracks are used only for local trains, 
 which make stops at intervals of about half a mile. 
 
 This line through the city has since been supplemented 
 by two lines around the urban district, one making the cir- 
 cuit to the north, and the other to the south. Alternate 
 trains on the central line run via the north and south rings. 
 
 Both Stadt and Ringbahn are as solidly and expensively 
 constructed as the main lines of railroad, and the stations 
 are large and convenient. Fares, too, are low from two 
 and a half to five cents, third class. But the trains are too 
 long and not frequent enough, and the service is provokingly 
 slow. Nevertheless, 124,000,000 passengers were carried in 
 1905. But with electrical equipment, and shorter, more 
 frequent, and more rapid trains, a vastly larger traffic could 
 be accommodated. 
 
 Omnibus traffic is still of considerable importance in Berlin. 
 Regular lines of omnibuses began running in 1846; and the 
 traffic increased steadily to 14,000,000 passengers in 1874. 
 Then it fell off for a few years, as the main street railway 
 lines came into operation, and took a subordinate place. But
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 
 
 307 
 
 from 1880 to 1900 the omnibus traffic increased at a faster 
 rate than the street railway; and since then it continues to 
 gain gradually. In 1905 there were 111,000,000 passengers. 
 
 A significant feature of the bus traffic in recent years is 
 that it is mainly for short distances, for which the fare is only 
 five pfennigs, or half the lowest street railway fare. More 
 than three-fourths of the passengers are of this class. It 
 seems probable that a similar system of busses with cheap 
 fares for short distance might develop a considerable traffic 
 in American cities. During the past year a number of gaso- 
 line motor busses have been introduced, and these may 
 replace the horse busses in a few years. 
 
 In America it would seem absurd to consider cab traffic as 
 an appreciable factor in local transportation. But it is such 
 in Berlin and other European cities. Under the taximeter 
 system, now mainly used, a ride for one or two persons costs 
 12 J cents for 800 metres, or approximately half a mile ; and 
 an additional 2| cents for each additional 400 meters. 
 
 No exact record of the number of cab passengers can be 
 given. But there are over 8000 cabs in commission, four 
 times as many as in 1865. And at the low estimate of ten 
 passengers each per day, the total yearly traffic amounts to 
 30,000,000. This is not a large proportion of the total 
 movement of 700,000,000 passengers in 1905, but it is worth 
 noting as one part of the situation. 
 
 The table below shows briefly the development of the 
 principal methods of transportation: 
 
 
 
 
 
 PASSENGERS 
 
 
 
 CABS 
 
 BUSSES 
 
 OMNIBUSES 
 
 STREET 
 RAILWAYS 
 
 STADT AND 
 RINOBAHN 
 
 1865 
 
 2260 
 
 192 
 
 
 
 
 1866 
 
 2423 
 
 208 
 
 12 502 337 
 
 960,551 
 
 
 1874 
 
 4190 
 
 159 
 
 14 696 976 
 
 8,758,153 
 
 
 1880 
 
 4733 
 
 167 
 
 10 781 391 
 
 51 557 037 
 
 
 1882 
 1890 
 1900 
 1905 
 
 4128 
 5488 
 8100 
 8093 
 
 134 
 241 
 662 
 
 13' 696', 560 
 27,804,123 
 80,568,714 
 111,000,000 
 
 65,218,792 
 140,957,271 
 280,349,160 
 454,000,000 
 
 9,347,850 
 33,891,912 
 80,409,436 
 124,000,000
 
 308 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Summarizing the Berlin transportation situation as a whole, 
 the most unsatisfactory features are the number of separate 
 operating companies, and the uncertainty as to the future 
 rights of the principal company under the grant from the 
 central government. But in the extension of facilities and 
 the development of traffic, Berlin makes a much better show- 
 ing than any of the other large cities of Europe, and compares 
 favorably with American cities. While in cheapness of 
 fares and financial benefit to the city treasury, Berlin seems 
 to be in a better position than any other city, European or 
 American. 
 
 These results show what can be accomplished under a 
 franchise system. And in many respects they are better 
 than under any system of municipal ownership and opera- 
 tion. But they are also better than in any other city where 
 the franchise system prevails. 
 
 LEIPZIG 
 
 Leipzig is, next to Hamburg, the largest German city which 
 is not at the same time the capital of an important state. 
 And it is of interest to note, at least briefly, how the munici- 
 pal government is affected by the fact that the city is not 
 the seat of the central government nor the residence of the 
 royal family. 
 
 In the capitals many of the attractive features of the cities 
 are due to the presence of the reigning houses and the govern- 
 ment. In their absence, Leipzig has less to show in the 
 way of palaces and museums than Dresden, which has about 
 the same population. But in other respects there is little 
 difference in the institutions that affect the residents of the 
 city. 
 
 As usual, the old city contains narrow and irregular streets. 
 But there has been much reconstruction work, notably the 
 boulevard ring which forms a complete circle of small parks 
 around the inner town. Nor are architectural features 
 wanting. On the ring are the massive new city hall and the
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 309 
 
 main buildings of the university. Near by are the university 
 library and the building of the imperial supreme court. All 
 of these are imposing and ornamental structures, which 
 improve the appearance of the city. 
 
 On the other hand, in the absence of the central government 
 and the royal family, the police in Leipzig are under the 
 immediate control of the municipal authorities. The Saxon 
 government, however, exercises supervision over the local 
 police, but at the same time grants to the city about one- 
 fourth of the cost of the police department. In America 
 opposition to state control of the police might be lessened if 
 the state also shared in the expense. 
 
 Leipzig has not adopted the policy of municipalization 
 quite so extensively as some other German cities. It has 
 municipal water- and gas- works ; and also slaughter-houses 
 and public markets. But the street railways and electric 
 plants are operated by two private companies. 
 
 The first street railway company began operation in 1872, 
 and in 1896 its lines were electrified. In the latter year 
 a new electric road was also put into operation. Both lines 
 have since been extended, and there are now over one hundred 
 miles of street railway lines. The fare is 2J cents, and there 
 are over 70,000,000 passengers carried. This is 50 per cent 
 more than in Munich, which has a larger population than 
 Leipzig, and is higher in proportion to population than in 
 Vienna. 
 
 MUNICH 
 
 In many ways Munich suggests Vienna on a smaller scale. 
 Both are South German capitals that were places of impor- 
 tance long before the rise of Berlin and other cities in northern 
 Germany. And both have grown rapidly during the past 
 fifty years. So that they combine some feature of a mediaeval 
 city with those of a modern municipality. Munich, however, 
 has comparatively little manufacturing industry or commerce, 
 and in this respect may be compared to Washington in the 
 United States.
 
 310 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 The municipal organization of Munich illustrates the com- 
 mon features of German cities; but there are also some pro- 
 visions peculiar to the Bavarian law. Although the Bava- 
 rian house of representatives is elected by universal suffrage, 
 the municipal electorate is restricted by a considerable tax 
 qualification, so that there are only 30,000 voters in a popu- 
 lation of half a million. But there is no division of the voters 
 into classes, as in Prussia and Austria. 
 
 Even with the limited electorate there are three active 
 parties, the Centre, the Liberals, and the Social-democrats, 
 the smallest of which polls nearly a fourth of the votes. In 
 the aggregate party vote in municipal elections, the Centre, 
 or Clericals, have a considerable plurality. But the members 
 of the municipal council are elected by districts; and the 
 party vote is so distributed that for the past twenty years 
 the Liberals have had a strong majority in the council. On 
 the other hand, the Centre has an overwhelming majority 
 in the Bavarian house of representatives; and although they 
 do not control the ministers, they are able to restrict the 
 local government to some extent. 
 
 Members of the municipal council are elected for a term 
 of nine years, one-third every three years. So this body 
 changes even more slowly than in other German states. 
 There is also, however, as in Prussian cities, a magistracy con- 
 sisting in part of permanent professional officials, and in part 
 of citizens. Both classes of magistrates are chosen by the 
 municipal council, but the professional salaried officials 
 must be confirmed by the central government. The mayor 
 is one of the professional officials, and like the others in this 
 class, is selected for life. 
 
 Physical reconstruction of the older part of Munich was 
 begun before the middle of the nineteenth century; and 
 perhaps on that account has not been so thoroughly accom- 
 plished as in Vienna. The -parked boulevard which occupies 
 the site of the old fortifications makes only a partial circuit 
 of the old town, and many narrow and irregular streets
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 311 
 
 still survive. Several of the old city gates have purposely 
 been left standing for their picturesque effect. But the new 
 sections of the city have been well laid out, with broad and 
 well-paved streets. 
 
 Indeed, in the matter of paving, Munich has adopted the 
 latest methods more rapidly than Vienna. In recent years 
 there has been laid many miles of asphalt and a good deal 
 of creosoted wooden blocks. There is also a large amount 
 of macadam. So that the travelling on most of the streets is 
 much more comfortable than on the granite blocks of other 
 cities. 
 
 Besides the parked boulevards there are a considerable 
 number of public gardens and larger parks. Many of these, 
 however, are not municipal, but belong to the royal family. 
 And as in other capitals, the palaces, museums, and govern- 
 ment buildings help to improve the general appearance and 
 attractiveness of the city. 
 
 Like most German cities, Munich has municipal slaughter- 
 houses and markets, and more recently gas and electric 
 works. But these are of course on a smaller scale than in 
 Vienna. The electric plants are the most important, as they 
 supply practically all the electrical energy in the city, in- 
 cluding that for the operation of the street railways. There 
 are two large generating plants, with a number of substations 
 where the high tension current is transformed to a lower 
 voltage for light and power purposes. All wires are under- 
 ground, except those for the street cars. 
 
 Street railways are still operated by a private company. 
 The original franchise was granted in 1857 for fifty years; 
 but there have been a number of subsequent contracts pro- 
 viding for extensions and the use of electric power. All of 
 these, however, expire with the original franchise in 1907, 
 when the question whether to lease or undertake municipal 
 operation will be decided, probably in favor of municipal 
 operation. 
 
 Munich has tried the American uniform fare, and aban-
 
 312 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 doned it to return to the zone system. When the street 
 railway system was electrified, the contract then made with 
 the city provided for a uniform fare of ten pfennigs or 2| 
 cents; but the city guaranteed a certain net income to the 
 company, estimated to be about 10 per cent of their capital. 
 Traffic increased, but not enough to yield this net income, 
 and the city had to pay considerable sums to the company. 
 After a few years, a new contract was made providing for 
 fares ranging from 2| to 5 cents. The number of passengers 
 carried fell off from 45,000,000 to less than 40,000,000 a year, 
 and has not yet regained the former figure. 
 
 Both in speed and comfort the service falls somewhat 
 short of that in Vienna. But although the company's rights 
 expire in a year, conditions are vastly better than in Chicago, 
 where the companies allowed their plant to run down as the 
 time for the expiration of their franchises drew near. That 
 conditions are better in Munich is doubtless due to the stipu- 
 lations in the contracts made from time to time. 
 
 One of the interesting municipal establishments in Munich 
 is the principal public bath-house. This is a handsome 
 building on the banks of the Isar, erected a few years ago at 
 a cost of $500,000. Three-fourths of this amount, however, 
 was a gift, and only one-fourth came from the city funds. 
 
 Within are bathing accommodations of every kind: a 
 swimming pool, shower baths, warm private baths, Turkish 
 baths, and a bathing place for dogs. Small fees are charged, 
 two and a half cents for a shower bath, four cents for the 
 swimming pool, twelve and a half cents for a private bath, 
 and thirty cents for a Turkish bath. The income pays 
 something more than operating expenses, but would not cover 
 interest on the investment if that had been borrowed. More 
 than 600,000 persons take baths in this establishment every 
 year. 
 
 BUDAPEST 
 
 Americans are apt to assume that western civilization is 
 confined to the countries where Germanic and Latin peoples
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 313 
 
 form a large part of the population, and that modern mu- 
 nicipal conditions are not to be found east of Vienna. But 
 even the briefest visit to Budapest, the capital and largest 
 city of Hungary, shows that it is a municipality of the first 
 rank, with material improvements beyond those of most 
 American cities. And its institutions and municipal under- 
 takings well deserve investigation, in spite of the difficulties 
 of distance and language. 
 
 Budapest is a city of 750,000 inhabitants, four-fifths of 
 whom have been added since the middle of the nineteenth 
 century. It is therefore not much larger, and is practically 
 no older, than St. Louis. And its geographical position on 
 the banks of a mighty continental river, and in the centre of 
 an immense agricultural region, is also similar to that of 
 the chief city of Missouri. But in almost everything that 
 goes to make a city comfortable and attractive, the Hungarian 
 capital far surpasses its American counterpart. 
 
 Some part of the pleasing impression that the city gives 
 to the visitor is undoubtedly due to natural features and the 
 public buildings of the national government. St. Louis has 
 nothing to compare with the castle hill and royal palaces on 
 the right side of the Danube, or the Parliament building on 
 the left bank. But, apart from these, the more distinctly 
 municipal features of Budapest are much more attractive, 
 and give the city a more finished appearance. While the 
 banks of the Mississippi at St. Louis remain neglected so far 
 as architectural appearances are concerned, those of the 
 Danube at Budapest are lined with massive stone embank- 
 ments and quays for shipping. Along the water front on each 
 side runs a river street, behind which are some of the largest 
 and finest buildings in the city. Five bridges span the river, 
 connecting the two parts of the city; and these are not only 
 useful, but are also artistic structures. The river front thus 
 forms one of the most inviting parts of the city; and the 
 constant movement of steamers and large steel freight barges 
 add a further element of variety to the panorama.
 
 314 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Turning from the river, the street system of Budapest is 
 well planned, with broad, main thoroughfares laid out with 
 reference to the lines of traffic, and side streets of comfortable 
 width. There is no evidence in most of the city of the 
 narrow lanes which are usual in most European cities, and 
 are also to be found in the older parts of some American cities. 
 The street pavements are solidly constructed and clean; but 
 the large granite blocks most generally used are too rough. 
 On some streets more recently paved, asphalt and creosoted 
 wooden blocks in concrete have been laid. Electric street 
 cars operated by private companies are frequent and com- 
 fortable. On some lines the overhead trolley is used; but 
 in most streets there are no overhead wires, and the under- 
 trolley is used, as in New York and Washington, but with 
 the underground conduit under one "oi the rails instead of 
 between them. In Budapest, too, is the first subway built 
 for street-car traffic, from which the larger American sub- 
 ways in Boston and New York have clearly been modelled. 
 It is built under Andrassy Street, one of the broad avenues 
 which forms the principal approach to the city park, and 
 was placed underground so as to retain this approach for 
 pleasure driving. 
 
 The city park, on the west side of the city, is compara- 
 tively small, but tastefully arranged. It contains a mena- 
 gerie, a small art museum, and a summer theatre, and also 
 refreshment houses. A much larger and more popular park 
 is St. Margaret's Island in the Danube, owned and embel- 
 lished by one of the grand dukes, but open to the general 
 public. 
 
 Budapest is celebrated for its public baths and also for 
 its hospitals, with which it is better supplied than any other 
 city of its size. The hospitals are supported by the city, 
 but are practically national institutions, and the municipality 
 is now asking the national government at least to share in 
 the expense of their management. 
 
 The sphere of municipal autonomy does not, however,
 
 MUNICIPAL CONDITIONS IN EUROPEAN CITIES 315 
 
 include the control over the local police. There is a national 
 force of gendarmerie, and also the Royal Hungarian Police; 
 and there is not even a supplementary force of municipal 
 guards, as in the Italian cities. 
 
 An imposing city hall is not included among the noteworthy 
 buildings of Budapest. The municipal government is housed 
 in an old barracks, which furnishes adequate room for the 
 various city officials. And from here the municipal house- 
 keeping is efficiently directed.
 
 XVII 
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 
 
 WITH all that has been published in America about Euro- 
 pean municipal government, Vienna has been largely ignored. 
 Yet even a brief examination is enough to show that this, 
 the fourth largest city in Europe, is also one of the most 
 important in its municipal development. Especially is this 
 true of the last decade, during which it is not too much to 
 say that its municipal history has been of greater significance 
 than that of any other city in Europe. 
 
 Some explanation may be offered for this neglect of Vienna. 
 The city is out of the way of the great tides of American 
 travel ; and most of the Americans who visit it are not those 
 likely to be interested in municipal institutions. Moreover, 
 the general history of Austria during the past forty years 
 conveys the impression that the country is not affected by 
 political movements in western Europe. The loss of inter- 
 national prestige since the military defeat at Koniggratz, 
 the internal race conflicts and the disputes with Hungary, 
 and the absence (until within a year) of any step in the direc- 
 tion of democratic suffrage, all suggest a situation where 
 political development of any kind is likely to be unknown. 
 
 Nevertheless, to repeat, during this period of forty years, 
 and more particularly in the last ten years, Vienna has a 
 remarkable record in its municipal affairs; and the same is 
 true in a smaller way of the other large cities of Austria. 
 Municipal autonomy has been more fully established than 
 in any other country of continental Europe; and indeed 
 except for the police in a few of the largest cities more 
 fully than in England or the United States. Population 
 and material prosperity have greatly increased. Physical 
 
 316
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 317 
 
 reconstruction and public improvements have been carried 
 out on a stupendous scale. In the later years, municipal 
 ownership of public utilities has, for good or ill, been rapidly 
 established, until Vienna has more municipalized undertak- 
 ings than any other city of its size. And these later develop- 
 ments in Vienna have been the direct result of a highly exciting 
 movement in local politics. 
 
 HOME RULE AND LOCAL ORGANIZATION 
 
 Municipal autonomy, or home rule, was provided for Aus- 
 trian cities by a statute of 1849, enacted as a result of the 
 revolutionary uprisings of the year before. But the reestab- 
 lishment of a reactionary policy led to a postponement in 
 the application of the statute; and it did not become effec- 
 tive until after the grant of provincial autonomy and the 
 establishment of provincial legislatures in 1860. The control 
 over municipal government was then transferred to the new 
 provincial diets, although the management of the police in 
 Vienna, Trieste, and Prague was retained under the imperial 
 government. 
 
 At this time the municipal electorate was narrowly restricted 
 by a considerable tax qualification, and in Vienna there 
 were only 18,000 voters. In 1867 and again in 1885 the tax 
 limit was reduced, increasing the number of voters in the 
 latter year to more than 50,000. The voters were, moreover, 
 divided into three classes, according to the amount of taxes 
 paid, so that the wealthier citizens had an influence much 
 greater than their numbers. But the basis of the class divi- 
 sions is different from that in the Prussian system. In Austria 
 it is dependent on the payment of a fixed amount of taxes; 
 so that with the increase of wealth the number of voters in 
 the upper classes tends to incease, while under the Prussian 
 system there is a steady reduction. 
 
 Important changes were made in the municipal organiza- 
 tion of Vienna in 1890. The city boundaries were further 
 extended to include the outlying suburbs; and at the same
 
 318 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 time a fourth class of voters was established, including prac- 
 tically all men who had a fixed residence in the city. But 
 this fourth class, which numbers nearly two-thirds of the 
 whole electorate, chooses only twenty-one members of the 
 municipal council, while the other three classes each elect 
 forty-eight members. The electoral system is thus still far 
 from an equal democracy. 
 
 The entire council consists of one hundred and sixty-five 
 members, elected for terms of six years, one-third retiring 
 every second year. They are elected in twenty-one perma- 
 nent districts, which represent the various historical com- 
 munes which make up the present city. Each district elects 
 at least one member from each class of voters; and each 
 district elects only one member from the fourth class. For 
 the three upper classes the number of members from each 
 district varies according to the distribution of population in 
 each class. Thus the wealthier districts elect several mem- 
 bers from the first class; some districts elect a number from 
 the second class; and some elect several members from the 
 third class. 
 
 As in European cities generally, the municipal council as 
 a whole does not attend to the details of administration, 
 but meets to vote appropriations and taxes, to decide on 
 important questions of policy, to elect officials, and to receive 
 and examine the reports of the municipal services. The 
 scope of its action is not limited by statute ; but it can under- 
 take any service it considers for the good of the city, provided 
 only it does not conflict with the higher governmental admin- 
 istration, and with the requirement that loans or the sale of 
 city property must be approved by the government. The 
 broad field of activity left to it may be indicated by noting 
 the fact that the recent municipalization of gas, electric 
 lighting, and street railways were all determined by a vote 
 of the council, with no special imperial or provincial legisla- 
 tion, and also without any direct popular vote. 
 
 Meetings of the council were formerly held about once a
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 319 
 
 week; but since the creation of the Stadtrath, they have 
 been less frequent, and now occur about once in two weeks. 
 
 The Stadtrath, a body established in 1890, is very different 
 from the Prussian board of municipal magistrates sometimes 
 called by the same name. In Vienna it is a smaller council, 
 or a large committee of the council, consisting of thirty-one 
 members (including the burgomasters) elected for terms of 
 six years. It contains none of the permanent technical and 
 professional officials of the city. It meets about three times 
 a week, appoints permanent officials, and exercises a general 
 supervision over current administration. It has two standing 
 committees, one on the law of citizenship, and one on the 
 discipline of municipal officials and employees. 
 
 A burgomaster and three vice-burgomasters are elected by 
 the general council from its own members, for terms of six 
 years. The burgomaster presides over the general council 
 and the Stadtrath, and is in practice the leader of the coun- 
 cil in its public policy. He is a political official ; and not, as 
 in the German Empire, a technical administrator, often chosen 
 for life. Under the statute the election of burgomaster 
 must be confirmed by the imperial government; but recent 
 history shows that in a contest between the council and the 
 government, the government will eventually yield. 
 
 In addition to these political elements, there is also the 
 permanent, professional and technical, executive officers and 
 employees. The chief of these is the " Magistrats-Direktor," 
 who with the heads of the various departments correspond 
 somewhat to the administrative officials in Prussian cities. 
 But in Vienna these are distinctly executive officers to carry 
 out the policy of the municipal council. The magistrates 
 are elected by the Stadtrath; but as their positions are per- 
 manent, changes can only be made as vacancies occur. 
 
 A few words must also be said about the municipal dis- 
 tricts. These are not only the districts for electing the mem- 
 bers of the council, but are also districts for local adminis- 
 tration with a sphere of local autonomy. They are thus of
 
 320 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 more importance than the arrondissements of Paris, but of 
 less than the metropolitan boroughs of London. In each 
 district there is elected a small council (from eighteen to 
 thirty members) by the voters of the first three classes, and 
 each district council elects a district chairman (bezirks- 
 vorsteher}. These bodies manage local public works, such 
 as street paving and cleaning; while the members also 
 cooperate with the central city departments in the adminis- 
 tration of poor relief and the work of school inspection. 
 
 THE LIBERAL REGIME 
 
 The foundations of modern Vienna were laid in the seven- 
 ties and early eighties, during the ascendency of the Liberals 
 in both local and imperial governments. During this period 
 vast schemes of reconstruction were carried out, new public 
 works and buildings were constructed on a magnificent scale, 
 surpassing even the Haussmannizing of Paris under the 
 Second Empire. Around the inner city, on the site of the 
 old fortifications, was laid out the Ring Strasse, one hundred 
 and eighty feet in width. Within the inner city, streets were 
 straightened and widened. In what was then the suburbs, 
 street plans for the extension of the city were elaborately 
 worked out. And a new water-supply was brought from 
 a distance of seventy miles. 
 
 In addition to such distinctly municipal improvements, 
 there was constructed largely by the emperor himself 
 the series of new public buildings and parks on both sides 
 of the Ring Strasse which make it " the finest street in the 
 world." In the centre of one group is the city hall, facing a 
 small park, flanked on one side by the Parliament building, 
 and on the other by the University. Opposite is the Court 
 Theatre, and next to this the gardens of the imperial court. 
 East of the gardens is the imperial palace; and opposite it 
 the new court house and the museums of art and natural 
 history. Still further around the Ring are the imperial opera- 
 house and the original municipal park. Moreover, through-
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 321 
 
 out the city, public parks and gardens have been established, 
 some by the city, some by the emperor, and some by other 
 members of the nobility. 
 
 To describe the achievements of this period would leave 
 no space for recent developments. But this brief mention 
 has been necessary to convey some impression of the general 
 appearance of the city, and the basis on which the later en- 
 terprises have been undertaken. The foundations were well 
 laid, and as a place to live in Vienna is one of the most com- 
 fortable and attractive cities in the world. 
 
 THE CHRISTIAN SOCIALISTS 
 
 As has been already noted, the recent expansion of munici- 
 pal functions in Vienna has been the direct result of a political 
 movement. This has been the rise to power of the Christian 
 Socialist party, whose policy in some respects seems a reaction 
 from the former liberalism, but at the same time may seem 
 to some to be in the direction of radical socialism. 
 
 Among the working-classes of Vienna the socialistic propa- 
 ganda spreading throughout Europe has been accepted to 
 some extent. And the Social-democratic party has for some 
 time been an active demonstrative organization, but (before 
 the latest election) with little influence either in local or 
 national government. The Christian Socialist party is en- 
 tirely distinct from the Social-democrats; and in fact, at the 
 present time, these are the two main opposing parties in 
 Vienna. 
 
 The Christian Socialist party has been formed on the basis 
 of religious, racial, and economic convictions or prejudices, 
 fused and welded by the organizing ability of Karl Lueger, 
 its undisputed leader and for the last ten years burgomaster 
 of Vienna. On the religious side it is intensely clerical, 
 strongly supporting and supported by the Catholic Church. 
 The racial factor is entirely distinct from the more general 
 race questions in Austria, and is a strong anti-semitic senti- 
 ment, fostered by the large number and growing influence of
 
 322 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the Jews in Vienna. Its economic basis is the opposition of 
 the great body of small traders and merchants to the power 
 of the great industries and wealthy capitalists, which have 
 been apparently promoted by the policy of the Liberals. 
 Each of these considerations appeals most strongly to the 
 middle classes, with whom the bulk of electoral power has 
 rested, but the party also includes large numbers of the labor- 
 ing classes, and now also many of the wealthy as the main 
 bulwark against the more radical socialists. 
 
 Karl Lueger, who has combined these factors into a highly 
 organized and disciplined party, is a man of striking per- 
 sonality. The son of a lower middle-class family, who be- 
 came a lawyer of moderate means, he represents in his own 
 person the convictions and interests of the classes which 
 form the core of his party. A man of strong physique and 
 a good speaker, he can wield great influence in public ad- 
 dresses. And he has shown the same capacity for organiza- 
 tion which forms one of the main sources of strength both of 
 the American political boss and the captain of industry. 
 
 He has of course been aided by many other men, whom it 
 would take too long to mention by name. The most numer- 
 ous group are the clergy, not the high dignitaries of the 
 church, but the parish priests, of the same peasant and middle- 
 class stock as those whose convictions and interests were 
 appealed to by the new party. With these and others the 
 work of organization was carried on steadily for several 
 years. 
 
 In 1894 the new party first gained control of the Vienna 
 municipal council. But the imperial government refused 
 to confirm Lueger's election as burgomaster; and when the 
 council elected him a second time, it was dissolved and a 
 new election ordered. In the new council Lueger and the 
 Christian Socialists were as strong as ever, and a compromise 
 was made. The former first vice-burgomaster was made 
 burgomaster; and Lueger was elected in his place, with the 
 understanding that in a few years he should become burgo-
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 323 
 
 master. In 1897 this was done; and since then he has re- 
 mained in full control of the city government. His majority 
 in the council steadily increased; and the old Liberal party 
 almost disappeared. In 1903 he was reflected for a second 
 term. 
 
 At the last election, however (in May, 1906), some seats 
 in the fourth class were lost to the Social-democrats. And 
 there are rumors that his overwhelming majority is in some 
 measure due to manipulation of the elections by some of 
 his lieutenants in the municipal districts. 
 
 Not only do Lueger and his party control the municipal 
 government, they also have a large majority in the provin- 
 cial diet of Lower Austria. This has prevented the provin- 
 cial control over municipal government from hindering the 
 execution of their plans. They also have a small but com- 
 pact following in the imperial Reichsrath; and in the con- 
 fused state of imperial politics this has induced the imperial 
 government not to oppose them too strongly in their man- 
 agement of municipal affairs. 
 
 MUNICIPAL OWNERSHIP IN VIENNA 
 
 Vienna has for many years had municipal ownership of 
 those undertakings most commonly under municipal manage- 
 ment in German cities. Not only waterworks, but also 
 slaughter-houses, markets, public baths, and savings banks 
 have been owned and managed by the city government. 
 But until the Lueger administration the gas and electric 
 light works and street railways were under the management 
 of private companies. 
 
 During the past eight years, however, the municipality 
 has entered all of these fields. In 1899 municipal gas-works 
 were established. In 1902 a municipal electric plant was 
 erected. And in 1903 the street railway system was taken 
 over by the city. 
 
 This policy of municipal ownership does not seem to have
 
 324 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 formed a prominent part of the announced programme of 
 the Christian Socialists. And it has been put into effect by 
 the municipal council without much popular discussion. It 
 may, however, be considered an application of the general 
 economic policy of the party to limit the power of large capi- 
 talists. 
 
 Very little objection to the municipal ownership policy 
 is expressed, even by those who have no sympathy with the 
 clerical and racial sentiments of the party in power. There 
 are a few critics on broad grounds of individualism, and 
 some opponents whose private interests have been affected. 
 But municipal functions have previously had so broad a 
 scope in German cities, that in the main this extension seems 
 at least to meet with acquiescence. 
 
 As early as 1873, when a former franchise for private gas- 
 works was approaching its limit, the establishment of a 
 municipal plant was proposed. But a new franchise was 
 then granted; and various plans to purchase the existing 
 works have led to no definite action. But in 1896 it was 
 definitely decided to construct a new municipal plant; and 
 three years later this was completed and began operation. 
 The contracts with the private companies have not as yet 
 expired ; and they continue to supply certain districts in the 
 city, and will for some years to come. 
 
 For the construction of the plant a loan of $12,000,000 was 
 made; and with the addition of a water-gas plant three years 
 later, the works are now valued at $13,000,000. The munic- 
 ipal plant furnishes gas to the central districts of the city, 
 and supplies more than two-thirds of the gas now used in 
 Vienna. 
 
 When the municipal plant was established, the price of 
 gas was slightly reduced; but there have been no further 
 reductions, and the rates for private use are approximately 
 $1.10 per thousand feet for .light, and 80 cents per thousand 
 feet for heat and power. In judging this price, the low cost 
 of labor and the high cost of coal must both be considered.
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 325 
 
 Coal is brought several hundred miles from Galicia and 
 Silesia, and with the high rates of freight costs $4.50 per 
 ton at the works. 
 
 Still another factor is the illuminating power. Not more 
 than twenty per cent of water-gas is used, in order to main- 
 tain the heating and lighting power of the gas. In America, 
 where water-gas is more largely used, there is much complaint 
 of the decline in illuminating power along with recent reduc- 
 tions in price. 
 
 Gas consumption for lighting purposes has increased but 
 slightly under municipal ownership. But the amount of 
 gas used for heat and power has more than quadrupled since 
 1900. The total amount of gas supplied from the municipal 
 plant in 1905 was 400,000,000 cubic feet. 
 
 Financially, the works are very profitable to the city. The 
 income from private consumers and from the sale of by- 
 products is more than sufficient to meet all expenses of 
 operation, with interest and sinking-fund charges. The 
 city gains by the value of public lighting, estimated at $200,- 
 000 a year, and an additional surplus of $400,000 a year. 
 But neither in the price to consumers nor in the more ex- 
 tended use of gas for lighting have the Vienna works brought 
 about the social advantages to the community sometimes 
 urged as one of the results of municipal ownership. 
 
 Construction of the municipal electric plant was begun 
 in 1900, and the works began operation in 1902. The plant 
 consists of two separate works on the same tract of land, 
 near the gas-works. One building contains the power plant 
 for the street railways; the other is for lighting and for power 
 to private consumers. But current may be transferred 
 from one to the other if needed. For the construction works 
 a loan of $6,000,000 was made by the city. 
 
 There are also three private electric companies in Vienna. 
 And while the municipal plant has rapidly extended its ser- 
 vice, in 1905 it furnished only about one-third of the electric 
 current sold to private consumers. Including the street rail-
 
 326 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 way service, the municipal plant furnishes about two-thirds 
 of the electric energy in Vienna. 
 
 As in the case of the gas-works, the municipal electric 
 plant is operated for financial profit rather than to extend 
 the use of electricity by low rates. On the face of the reports 
 a large profit is shown. In 1905, after deducting operating 
 expenses, interest, and depreciation charges, the net surplus 
 was $500,000, more than 8 per cent of the capital invest- 
 ment, and 30 per cent of the gross income. 
 
 But the income is in large part an estimated revenue from 
 the current used for public purposes. Nearly half of the 
 total income is for power furnished to the street railway 
 service. This is charged at the rate of three cents a kilowatt 
 hour, compared to seven cents as the average rate received 
 from private consumers. This seems to be about cost; and 
 on the surface does not seem to be too high a charge for the 
 street railway current, which is two-thirds of the output of 
 the whole plant. But a small change in the rate charged 
 against the street railway service would modify so much 
 the financial results of the electric plant, that safe conclusions 
 can hardly be drawn from the published reports. 
 
 Of more importance than either the gas or electric plants 
 has been the municipalization of the street railways in 
 Vienna. It is the largest municipal street railway system in 
 the world, and one of the most recent. And on both accounts 
 an examination of the Vienna enterprise should be of value 
 for the present discussion in the United States. 
 
 Before the city government took up this work there were 
 two street railway companies, operating in 1899 seventy 
 miles of line and carrying 85,000,000 passengers. Only a few 
 lines had been electrified. In that year the city received 
 the necessary authority from the imperial railroad department 
 to construct a new electrical system, including the rebuild- 
 ing of the lines of the larger of the two companies and a 
 large number of new lines. The company went into liquida- 
 tion and disposed of its lines and rights to the city.
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 327 
 
 A contract for the new construction work and temporary 
 operation of the lines was made with the Siemens and Halske 
 Company. In 1902 the lines of the smaller company were 
 also transferred to the city. And on July 1, 1903, the mu- 
 nicipal government took over from the contractor the opera- 
 tion of the whole system. 
 
 For the purchase of the old lines and new construction 
 and equipment, the city issued a loan of $25,000,000. The 
 mileage is already double that in 1899, and new lines are 
 being steadily constructed. No cars run through the old 
 inner city, where the streets are still too narrow for car tracks. 
 But most of the lines run at least to the Ring Strasse, and 
 many of them run for some distance on the Ring. This 
 facilitates transfers from one line to another; so that one 
 may go from one part of the city to another in most cases 
 with one change of cars. The equipment is entirely new, 
 and the cars are larger than in other European cities. With 
 the wide streets a more rapid service is furnished. 
 
 The schedule of fares has been revised and somewhat 
 reduced. In the morning, before half-past seven, there is a 
 uniform rate of two cents. Later in the day the lowest 
 fare is two and a half cents; for longer distances it is four 
 cents; and for a few of the longest journeys six cents is 
 charged. On Sundays and holidays there is a uniform fare 
 of four cents. These fares include transfers from one line to 
 another within the distance limits. The average fare paid is 
 slightly under three cents. 
 
 Since municipal management there has been a rapid in- 
 crease of traffic. In 1905 the total number of passengers 
 was 180,000,000, more than double that in 1899. There is 
 no complaint about the service, and a general opinion that 
 it is much better than under the private companies. 
 
 At the same time it should be noted that the service is 
 not so extensive in proportion to population as in the large 
 American cities. The mileage of lines is less, and the average 
 distance travelled by each passenger is a good deal less. This
 
 328 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 must be taken into account in considering the lower rates 
 of fare. And the total number of passengers is much smaller 
 in proportion to population, even if the traffic on the local 
 elevated and underground steam lines is considered. These 
 facts indicate that a large share of the population either 
 live near their work or walk long distances. 
 
 In fact Vienna is a city of tenement houses, which enable 
 a large population to live in a comparatively small area. 
 Yet the dwelling conditions seem to be fairly satisfactory. 
 The construction of such buildings is strictly regulated so 
 as to insure plenty of light and air. The frequent parks 
 furnish an abundance of open spaces. And there is appar- 
 ently no great amount of crowding. 
 
 On the financial side, municipal operation has been in 
 force too brief a period to speak with assurance. On the 
 face of the reports there is a considerable surplus after pay- 
 ing operating expenses and interest. In 1904 this amounted 
 to $660,000; and after using half of this for extensions and 
 certain other payments, the other half was turned into the 
 general city treasury. 
 
 But there is no allowance for depreciation or a sinking- 
 fund to pay off the cost of construction. And if one of these 
 were included, as should be done, the whole surplus would 
 easily be absorbed. The question of the charge for the 
 electric current must also be considered. But it at least 
 seems clear that no large profits are being earned for the 
 city from the street railway service, as from the gas and elec- 
 tric plants. 
 
 Much might also be written about other municipal enter- 
 prises in Vienna under the present regime. In June, 1906, 
 there was opened a new home for the aged poor, con- 
 sisting of a group of twenty large buildings, erected in the 
 outskirts of the city at a cost of $4,500,000. Many additional 
 small parks have been added; and a third boulevard around 
 the city is projected. A good deal of asphalt and wooden- 
 block pavement has been laid, although most of the streets
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN VIENNA 329 
 
 are still paved with rough granite blocks. And a new water- 
 supply is under construction, bringing water from the Styrian 
 Alps, a hundred and fifty miles away. But these and other 
 undertakings must be passed over at this time. 
 
 Some notice must, however, be given to the influence of 
 politics on the municipal administration. It is here that the 
 pronounced anti-semitic sentiments of the party in power 
 come into play. The rule of permanence in the municipal 
 service has been too firmly established in Vienna, as in 
 other Germanic cities, to permit of anything like a whole- 
 sale removal of officials and employees for racial or other 
 political reasons. But it seems clear that no Jew can hope 
 for any appointment in the municipal service under the 
 Lueger rule. And it is openly asserted that in the exercise 
 of their discretionary powers, the officials do not hesitate to 
 refuse privileges to the members of the hated race which are 
 readily granted to others. 
 
 This aspect of the municipal situation in Vienna has a 
 special significance to Americans. It means that the mu- 
 nicipal administration in general, and more specifically the 
 experiment in municipal ownership, is being conducted with 
 something like the dangers of political influences so prev- 
 alent in American city government. And for that reason 
 future developments in Vienna should be watched with 
 interest. But one of the dangers that are feared in America 
 seems as yet to be entirely absent. There are no open charges 
 of anything like corruption in the municipal government.
 
 XVIII 
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 
 
 ITALIAN cities offer so much of interest to the traveller 
 and the student of art and archaeology in their ancient and 
 mediaeval monuments that they are seldom considered with 
 reference to their modern municipal conditions. Indeed until 
 after the establishment of the present kingdom the conditions 
 of Italian city life were so unattractive to say the least 
 as to offer no field for the student of municipal problems. 
 And it is also true that none of the Italian cities belong to 
 the class of great metropolitan communities of more than 
 a million population, where municipal affairs are of the great- 
 est interest and importance. 
 
 Nevertheless, Italy contains half a dozen large cities, in- 
 creasing in population and importance, where the problems 
 of modern municipal life have to be faced. In recent years 
 most of these cities have turned with more or less vigor to 
 the task of looking after the needs and comfort of their in- 
 habitants. And an examination of their achievements is 
 not without value to those interested in American municipal 
 affairs. 
 
 Before looking at conditions in particular cities, it will 
 be well to note some of the general characteristics of city 
 government in Italy. All of the cities, and also the country 
 towns or communes, are governed under one uniform law, 
 providing a simple system of municipal organization, with 
 a large degree of local autonomy. There are, however, some 
 important limitations on municipal activity, notably the 
 police system of the national government; while there is 
 also a considerable amount of administrative supervision 
 over the municipal authorities. 
 
 330
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 331 
 
 Every city has a municipal council varying in the number 
 of members with the population of the city. The larger 
 cities have from 60 to 80 members. These are elected at 
 large, or on a general ticket ; and there are no ward aldermen, 
 as in American and English municipalities. But in order 
 to prevent one party from electing all the members of the 
 council, a system of limited voting is established. Under 
 this system, each voter may vote for not more than four- 
 fifths of the whole number of councillors to be elected; and 
 one-fifth therefore represent the minority. Until 1906 coun- 
 cilmen were elected for four years, one-half of the whole 
 number every second year. But under a new statute one- 
 third of the members will be elected every second year for 
 a term of six years. 
 
 The council votes the budget and acts on the larger ques- 
 tions of municipal policy. But it does not, as a whole, attend 
 to the details of administration. For the latter purpose 
 there are elected by the council, from its own members, 
 a syndic corresponding to the mayor and an executive 
 committee known collectively as the giunta, while the indi- 
 vidual members are called assessors. Each assessor is 
 assigned to one branch of municipal affairs; while acting 
 together as the giunta they pass local ordinances, make 
 appointments, and decide on the more important questions 
 of current administration. 
 
 Neither the assessors nor the other members of the council 
 receive any salary. There are also salaried technical officers 
 at the head of each body of municipal employees; and one 
 of the most important offices is that of the secretary-general, 
 who corresponds somewhat to the English town clerk. 
 The salaried officials and employees form a permanent civil 
 service, as a general rule; but there have been exceptional 
 cases of political appointments and removals in Naples and 
 other cities of southern Italy. 
 
 Municipal functions in Italian cities include, in the first 
 place, the usual public works for the care of the streets and
 
 332 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 drainage. Usually also the water-supply is municipal. 
 There are also municipal markets, cemeteries, and hospitals. 
 A number of cities have municipal electric light plants. A 
 few, including the important city of Bologna, have municipal 
 gas-plants. Milan owns the local street railway system, 
 but has leased the operation to a private company. Some 
 questions as to the power of cities to engage in such under- 
 takings led to the passage of a law in 1904 distinctly au- 
 thorizing the municipalization of public utilities. The local 
 management of schools also comes under the municipal 
 government; but here there is a high degree of central con- 
 trol. Public charities are under the control of special com- 
 missions, known as "congregations of charity," the members 
 of which are often chosen by the municipal council. 
 
 The police system in Italy is peculiar, and at first seems 
 rather complicated. In the large cities three different kinds 
 of policemen are in evidence, the carbinieri, the guards 
 of public security, and the municipal guards. The carbi- 
 nieri correspond to the French gendarmerie. They are 
 strictly a national force, under the control of the minister 
 of war, but quite distinct from the regular army. Mounted 
 carbinieri police the country districts. In the cities, the 
 carbinieri are to be seen guarding public buildings, and are 
 also on duty wherever large assemblies of people are gathered, 
 as during processions or at public assemblies; and in cases 
 of riot they are used somewhat as our state militia. 
 
 The guards of public security are also a national force, 
 but under the general control of the minister of the interior, 
 and under the immediate direction of the prefect in each 
 province. They look after the more serious offences against 
 the criminal law, including a large amount of detective 
 work. In many small cities, where there are no municipal 
 guards, the guards of public security also perform their 
 functions. 
 
 Municipal guards are, however, provided by the municipal 
 authorities in all of the larger cities. Their special functions
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 333 
 
 are to enforce the municipal ordinances for the regulation 
 of street traffic, building construction, and sanitation. They 
 have also the power of arresting violators of the criminal 
 law; but in this respect they simply supplement and do not 
 replace the national police. 
 
 This triple system seems to offer opportunities for con- 
 stant friction, but in practice apparently works without 
 much difficulty. It is certainly much more highly central- 
 ized than in most American cities; and the important police 
 authority is not to be found in the local government, but 
 is the prefect of the province, or the police commissioner 
 appointed by him. 
 
 In addition to the police powers of the prefects, the local 
 authorities are supervised in the discharge of their functions. 
 Municipal ordinances must be approved by the giunta or 
 executive council of the province, which is, however, elected 
 in the province, and represents provincial rather than national 
 supervision. Legal questions, arising in contested elections, 
 tax assessments, etc., are determined in the first instance by 
 provincial administrative courts, but appeals may be taken 
 to the central administrative court for the kingdom. And 
 the accounts of every city and commune must be examined 
 and approved by agents of the national government, a system 
 which secures a uniform system of accounts, and keeps the 
 local authorities within the restrictions established by law. 
 
 NAPLES 
 
 Naples, the first city in Italy to be visited by an American 
 going to Europe by the southern route, may in some respects 
 be compared to New York. It is the largest city in Italy, 
 and its principal seaport. And its city government in the 
 past has been as notoriously bad as that of the worst Tam- 
 many administration. As in New York, conditions in recent 
 years show a marked improvement. But even yet there is 
 but little in Naples to attract favorable notice, and much less 
 than the more progressive communities further to the north.
 
 334 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 What first attracts attention is the almost complete absence 
 of terminal facilities for the shipping which centres here. 
 A harbor has been constructed, but there are no wharves for 
 the larger ships, and these must anchor in the harbor, and 
 transfer passengers and freight by small boats to the shore. 
 
 Landed, and having passed the dust and confusion of the 
 custom-house, the visitor next becomes aware of the narrow, 
 crooked, ill-paved, and dirty streets. In the older part of 
 Naples most of the public ways cannot be called streets, 
 but are simply narrow lanes or passages. Most of them have 
 no sidewalks, and many are not wide enough for wheeled 
 vehicles. In the hilly districts there are many lanes for foot 
 passengers so steep that the road is a series of steps, on which 
 the crowded tenements open. The more important streets are 
 often less than forty feet in width ; and even in the new resi- 
 dence districts, boulevards are seldom over fifty feet across. 
 There is nothing like a systematic arrangement of the streets, 
 and little has been done as in other large European cities 
 to remedy the lack of main thoroughfares in the older 
 sections by opening new streets through the congested dis- 
 tricts. The only relief is that afforded by the frequent 
 "squares" or piazzas, where several streets come together. 
 
 Street pavements are still laid with large blocks of lava, 
 about two feet by three. Except for the more regular shape 
 of the blocks, they do not differ from the pavements in 
 Pompeii, laid eighteen centuries ago. At best they make 
 a rough road; and where they are worn, a carriage drive is 
 anything but a pleasure. Dust, and in rainy weather mud, 
 add much to the discomfort, although it is evident that there 
 is some attempt at cleaning the streets and lanes. 
 
 A private company operates electric cars through most 
 of the more important streets, and omnibus lines on the 
 others. But the total mileage falls far short of that in an 
 American city of half the size. The service is rather slow 
 and infrequent. Open cars are run in summer. On the 
 principal lines there are cars every few minutes, but on some
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 335 
 
 routes one may have to wait ten or fifteen minutes. Fares 
 are graded according to distance, from two to five cents, the 
 ordinary ride costing three or four cents. There are two 
 classes recognized, first-class passengers having cushioned 
 seats in the open cars. 
 
 But the local transportation problem is greatly affected 
 by the cab service. At every piazza, are to be found small 
 cabriolets, driven by the little Neapolitan horses, which 
 carry one or two passengers from one place to another within 
 the city for the sum of fourteen cents unless the driver 
 can make a better bargain with the unwary American. With 
 thousands of these cabriolets, only the poorer classes use the 
 street cars; and the volume of traffic is much less than that 
 in American cities. 
 
 In other respects modern municipal improvements have 
 been established in Naples, but generally on a small scale. 
 The Villa Nazionale is a charming park, of moderate dimen- 
 sions, facing on the bay. Here is located the well-known 
 Aquarium, with its curious and interesting specimens of marine 
 life. And here a band of music plays every evening to thou- 
 sands of Neapolitans. Some of the more important streets 
 in the centre of the city are lit by electricity. And an ex- 
 cellent water supply has been secured from the distant hills. 
 
 Nevertheless, some conditions of life for the great mass of 
 the people seem almost intolerable to an American. In the 
 warm southern climate it takes little to maintain existence; 
 and the population grows luxuriantly, like the vegetation 
 on the slopes of Vesuvius. Huddled together in crowded 
 tenements, most of the people spend the greater part of their 
 time in the open air. The streets and alleys are constantly 
 thronged, not only with hucksters and lazy beggars, but also 
 with women and children attending to their private occupa- 
 tions. While through it all, the constant clatter of the cabs 
 and the din of countless noises creates a confusion that is 
 almost unimaginable. 
 
 The seat of the municipal government is in a building of
 
 336 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 the early part of the nineteenth century, facing one of the 
 largest open squares, called the Piazza di Municipio. The 
 city government, as already noted, has been at times con- 
 trolled by corrupt and dishonest officials. But, aided by 
 the active supervision of the central government, the 
 present situation shows a good deal of improvement, and 
 there are hopeful signs for the future. 
 
 ROME 
 
 Coming to Rome from Naples, the visitor perceives at once 
 a great improvement in municipal conditions; and further 
 examination confirms the impression that in Rome municipal 
 administration has reached a high standard of excellence. 
 As in most European cities, the railway terminal and its 
 immediate surroundings form an attractive approach, and 
 in that respect contrasts very favorably with the railroad 
 entrances to many American cities. Moreover, the newer 
 sections of Rome are well laid out, with broad and well-kept 
 thoroughfares. In the older sections near the river will be 
 found narrow lanes and passages; but even through these 
 there have been opened new avenues for the main lines of 
 traffic. And everywhere the streets and alleys are sub- 
 stantially paved, and the pavements are clean and in excel- 
 lent repair. 
 
 Most of the streets are paved with stone blocks of a peculiar 
 kind. Each block is about five inches square on the surface, 
 and about eight inches deep, and is slightly wedge-shaped, 
 so that the bottom is somewhat smaller than the top surface. 
 Whether the odd shape of the blocks or the good quality of 
 the work of laying the pavements deserves the most credit, 
 the pavement is certainly more satisfactory than other stone 
 block pavements. A few streets in Rome are paved with 
 wooden blocks laid on concrete, and these offer a smoother 
 but less durable surface. 
 
 In some of the street-improvement work that has been 
 done in Rome, the city has been aided financially by the
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 337 
 
 national government, which has been interested in making 
 the capital an attractive centre. This aid has been given 
 mainly in opening up new avenues through the older, crowded 
 sections of the city ; and a new work of this kind now under 
 way is the enlargement of the Venetian Square. Another 
 important improvement completed within a few years is the 
 Quirinal Tunnel, which is in fact a broad street carried under 
 the royal palaces and gardens on Quirinal Hill, and forming 
 a main thoroughfare from the northern to the central part of 
 the city. 
 
 The street railway service in Rome is in the hands of 
 a private company, and is distinctly better than in Naples. 
 There are more lines, and more frequent cars, and the ser- 
 vice is quicker. There is only one class of passengers. Fares 
 are based on the zone system, ranging from two to five cents. 
 But there are no open cars in summer, and in many ways 
 the service is inferior to that in most American cities. 
 
 Public squares or piazzas are of frequent occurrence, and 
 form centres of business and places of public resort, especially 
 in the afternoon and evening. But Rome is very inade- 
 quately supplied with public parks. There are many beauti- 
 ful private parks within the palaces of the older Roman 
 nobility, and also the royal gardens ; but these are all behind 
 high walls, and are not accessible to the general public, and 
 there are no small public parks within the city. The most 
 important park open to the public is the Villa Borghese, just 
 outside the city walls. This is a large wooded estate, and 
 is a favorite resort for the modern Romans. But there are 
 no provisions for games, and few accommodations for the 
 people who come there. It may be that the Italians prefer 
 the life of the piazzas within the city, but to an outsider it 
 would seem that more of the open country would be better 
 for the physical life of the people. 
 
 In its architectural monuments and its collections of paint- 
 ings and sculpture, Rome is one of the greatest centres of 
 the world. All of these collections, which attract the attention
 
 338 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 of the visitors, are also open to the inhabitants of Rome on 
 payment of the usual fees. And in this respect the resident 
 of Rome has an almost unsurpassed opportunity for educa- 
 tion in art and archaeology. Most of the collections, how- 
 ever, are not municipal, but are owned by the national 
 government, by the churches, and by private families. 
 
 The city hall of Rome occupies a most interesting historical 
 position, on the top of the Capitoline Hill, the site of the 
 ancient Capitol, and overlooking the excavated ruins of the 
 Roman Forum. The foundation walls of the present build- 
 ing date from the fifth century A.D. ; but the building itself 
 was erected in the later Middle Ages and is of no special im- 
 portance, while the interior is dark and gloomy. But it 
 speaks well for the city government that it has devoted its 
 energies to the physical improvement of the city rather than 
 to housing itself in a new and magnificent building. 
 
 There is little of special interest to be said about the city 
 officials and local politics of Rome. The municipality has 
 the same autonomous powers as other Italian cities, and 
 in that respect is in a somewhat more independent position 
 than the capitals of other European countries. The mystic 
 letters S. P. Q. R. still appear in official documents, but have 
 no special significance, as the legal titles for the local officials 
 are those established by the modern municipal code. It is 
 a municipal government that can show large, substantial 
 results since the overthrow of the temporal power of the 
 Pope; but these have been secured with comparatively little 
 excitement, and local politics of to-day are less active than 
 in some of the other Italian cities. 
 
 FLORENCE 
 
 Probably Florence is the Italian city best known to Ameri- 
 cans, who come here in large numbers as the focus of modern 
 art and literature in Italy. In many respects it is an attractive 
 city, and its recent municipal history offers a good deal of
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 339 
 
 interest. But from this point of view it is comparatively 
 of less importance than some of the larger cities. 
 
 In the older part of the town the streets are narrow, but 
 more regularly laid out than in the older sections of other 
 Italian cities. In the newer districts the streets are wider, 
 while the encircling boulevard which follows the line of the 
 old ramparts is a broad avenue. The street pavements are 
 much better than in Naples, but inferior to those of Rome. 
 The public squares and public parks are larger and more 
 attractive than in either of the more southern cities. The 
 most important parks are the Boboli Gardens, connected with 
 the royal palace, and the Cascine, to the west of the city along 
 the banks of the Arno. 
 
 These physical features are largely the result of important 
 improvement schemes begun in the late sixties, when Florence 
 was the capital of Italy. But the transfer of the capital to 
 Rome after 1870 was a serious financial loss to Florence, 
 and the cost of the improvements became a heavy burden, 
 which led to a crisis in municipal finances in 1879 and 1880. 
 As a result, while the city has the improvements begun in the 
 earlier period, a more cautious policy has had to be followed 
 in recent years. 
 
 Florence has had some interesting contests with private 
 lighting corporations. About 1854 a long-term franchise was 
 granted to a gas company, which the company claimed gave 
 it a monopoly of both public and private lighting. When 
 it was proposed to introduce electric lighting, the gas com- 
 pany claimed this was an infringement of its privileges; but 
 after a long contest in the courts it was decided that the 
 city could not grant a monopoly of private lighting. Sub- 
 sequently the city established an electric light plant, in con- 
 nection with the waterworks, for public lighting; and after 
 another legal battle their power to do this was sustained, 
 and has been more clearly confirmed by the recent law on 
 municipal undertakings. 
 
 There are a number of electric street railway lines in
 
 340 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Florence; but many parts of the city are not covered, and 
 the service is rather slow. Fares are, as usual, based on the 
 zone system, and range from two to five cents. The owner- 
 ship of the lines has recently been transferred to a Belgian 
 company, which promises to furnish a better service. Dur- 
 ing 1906 new franchises have been granted for additional 
 lines, extending the rights of the company for forty years. 
 
 The municipal government of Florence is controlled by 
 a combination of Clericals and Moderates, which pursues 
 a conservative policy. Popular interest in municipal 
 elections has been slight; but the socialists are becoming 
 more active, and the recent local campaigns correspondingly 
 
 more vigorous. 
 
 MILAN 
 
 Municipal government in Milan is by far more interesting 
 to an American than in any other Italian city. It is the 
 second largest city in Italy; but it is the most active in its 
 private business enterprises, and in some respects may be 
 compared to Chicago on a smaller scale. In municipal affairs 
 it has been the most aggressive in extending the scope of 
 municipal functions, while the local elections have been the 
 occasions for some striking political combinations and heated 
 campaigns. 
 
 In its physical appearance Milan shows the results of im- 
 portant schemes of street improvements. The large square 
 in front of the famous cathedral is now the centre of the city, 
 and from this the important streets have been constructed 
 on the radial plan. A boulevard has taken the place of the 
 old fortifications around the city. But in the heart of the 
 city there are still many narrow streets and lanes. 
 
 Street paving in Milan is, however, much inferior to that in 
 Rome. There is a small amount of asphalt. But most of 
 the principal streets are paved with larger stone blocks, as 
 in Naples and Florence, while many streets are still paved 
 with cobblestones. The cobblestones are well laid, and 
 by constant repair these pavements are kept in a tolerable
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 341 
 
 condition. All of the streets, too, are thoroughly cleaned. 
 But as a whole, the pavements are not what might be ex- 
 pected in a city that is in other respects the most advanced 
 in Italy. 
 
 As in other Italian cities, public parks are few and of lim- 
 ited dimensions. Cathedral Square, unlike other piazzas, is a 
 small park. The Public Gardens, the best in Italy, form 
 a beautiful park well within the city. The ground for a 
 larger park has been reserved for some time near the old 
 castle. But this has never been embellished in any way; 
 and during the summer of 1906 the larger part of this area 
 was occupied by the Exposition then being held. 
 
 Street Railway System 
 
 Perhaps the most interesting feature in the municipal 
 affairs of Milan is the municipal ownership of the street rail- 
 way system, and the contract for its operation by a private 
 corporation. Before this contract the operating company 
 paid a lump sum of $200,000 to the city, and had almost 
 unlimited control of the service. But under the present 
 contract, which went into force in 1897 for twenty years, not 
 only is the municipal ownership of the tracks clearly em- 
 phasized, but the city government retains a large measure of 
 continuous control over the service, without, however, having 
 the direct management of the force of employees. 
 
 The municipality provides at its own expense the tracks 
 in the streets, and can extend these at its own pleasure; 
 and all the tracks remain the exclusive property of the city. 
 The operating company, on the other hand, agrees to operate 
 cars by electric traction over all the lines built by the city; 
 and for that purpose to furnish and maintain the electrical 
 plant and apparatus, the rolling stock, and the operating 
 personnel. Moreover, the plans and specifications for any 
 construction work by the company must be submitted to 
 and approved by the giunta, or executive committee of the 
 municipal council.
 
 342 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 Service must be furnished by the company for eighteen 
 hours a day during the summer, and seventeen hours in the 
 winter. The municipality may regulate the number of cars 
 on each line, and the daily mileage of each car, thus con- 
 trolling the speed of the traffic. 
 
 Rates of fare are established on a uniform basis, instead 
 of the zone system usual in European cities. The ordinary 
 fare is ten centesimi, or two cents; but during two hours 
 every day the fare is only five centesimi, or one cent. 
 
 The arrangements for payments between the city and 
 company involve a somewhat complicated calculation. In 
 the first place the municipality contributes a certain amount 
 on the basis of car mileage, with a provision authorizing 
 a reduction in the rate if the cost of operation is reduced. 
 On the other hand, the city receives forty per cent of the in- 
 come of the company, after deducting the above-mentioned 
 compensation, and a track mileage estimate. It is not easy to 
 determine from these provisions what the net results will be to 
 the city. But in fact the payments to the city have shown 
 a very large increase over those under the previous contract. 
 
 There are also provisions regulating the relations between 
 the company and its employees. No man may work more 
 than ten hours a day, in periods of not over six hours, and 
 each man is to have four days of rest in each month. Wages 
 are to be not less than 30 centesimi (6 cents an hour) or three 
 lire (60 cents a day). And a reserve fund for insurance and 
 retiring allowances is established by fixed contributions from 
 the company, the city, and the employees. 
 
 In addition to the conditions specified in the contract, 
 the company must obey all orders and regulations estab- 
 lished for public security or sanitation by the municipal 
 authorities, or imposed by the prefect or higher governmental 
 officials. The city also has the right to run cars itself for 
 municipal purposes, such as street watering, and may grant 
 rights to other companies to operate cars by other than elec- 
 trical traction.
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 343 
 
 This contract has now been in operation for ten years, 
 and under it Milan has by far the best street railway system 
 in Italy. There are lines to all parts of the city, the cars 
 are neat and comfortable, and the service is frequent and 
 rapid. The statistics of traffic show that the number of 
 passengers has doubled since 1897, and was over 100,000,000 
 during the year 1906. The company and the city have 
 worked together harmoniously, partly, perhaps, because the 
 company is largely made up of local capitalists who have 
 close personal relations with the city officials. 
 
 In some respects, however, the service is not so good as 
 in some American cities. Nearly all the lines run to Cathe- 
 dral Square. This arrangement makes transfers from one 
 line to another convenient; but as no transfer checks are 
 given, two fares must be paid, and there is practically a zone 
 system for those who wish to cross the city. More objection- 
 able is the congestion of cars in Cathedral Square, causing 
 a good deal of confusion, and blocking traffic of all sorts. It 
 would improve the situation to establish a series of through 
 lines running from one side of the city across the square to 
 the other. 
 
 Working-class Dwellings 
 
 Another problem of the greatest importance in Italy, which 
 the Milan city government has more recently taken up, is 
 that of improving the dwelling-house conditions of the work- 
 ing-classes. The growth of population and the influx of 
 factory hands cause an increasing demand for dwelling accom- 
 modations ; and with the crowded conditions that prevail in 
 Milan, as in other Italian cities, the municipal authorities 
 have felt that they must take action to relieve the situation. 
 
 Already houses for several hundred families have been 
 built in the outskirts, and more houses for a larger number 
 are now under construction. In this work the effort has not 
 been, as in England, to meet the needs of the poorest classes, 
 but to build model houses for the better class of mechanics
 
 344 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and skilled laborers. And the financial reports show that 
 thus far this work has been self-sustaining. 
 
 A new and somewhat different project has just recently 
 been undertaken. The city has purchased a tract of land 
 beyond the built-up district, where it proposes to lay out and 
 construct streets and other material improvements, including 
 an extension of the street railway system. Certain tracts 
 of land will then be reserved for schoolhouses and other 
 public buildings and purposes, and the remainder will then 
 be offered for sale. The whole scheme may almost be called 
 a real estate speculation. And one of the significant steps 
 leading up to this undertaking was the submission of the 
 proposition to a referendum vote of the electors, at which 
 it was adopted by a large majority. 
 
 Municipal Politics 
 
 Municipal elections in Milan have been active and exciting, 
 especially during the past few years. And they are of interest 
 not only as illustrations of political methods in general, but 
 also in showing how far the new municipal enterprises noted 
 above have been due to a definite political propaganda. 
 
 As in other large Italian cities, local elections have generally 
 been contested by the national parties, though usually on 
 local issues. For forty years before 1900 the city govern- 
 ment of Milan was controlled by a rather indefinite union of 
 Moderates, Conservatives, and Liberals. In opposition were 
 three other parties, the Clericals, the Radical-democrats, 
 and the Socialists. And it was in this period that the new 
 contract for the operation of the street railway system was 
 adopted. 
 
 In 1900 the Socialists and Radical-democrats united for 
 the municipal elections, under the name of the Union of 
 Popular Parties; and this fusion was successful at this elec- 
 tion and also two years later. This situation led to another 
 fusion of the Moderates and Clericals, under the name of the 
 Electoral Federation; and in November, 1904, after the strikes
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 345 
 
 of the previous summer, the Federation elected its candidates 
 to the municipal council. This result was accepted by the 
 Socialist and Radical members of the council whose terms 
 had not expired, as a vote of lack of confidence; and they 
 resigned as would an English Cabinet after a defeat in the 
 House of Commons. At the special election in January, 
 1905, to fill the vacancies, the Federation was again success- 
 ful ; and has thus now complete political control of the mu- 
 nicipal government, except for the minority representation 
 on the council secured by the system of limited voting. 
 
 In practice there seems to be but little difference in the 
 municipal policies of these two local parties, for the com- 
 binations are only made for local elections. Under the 
 Socialist-Radical regime the scheme for working-house dwell- 
 ings was begun. But this has been continued and extended 
 by the Federation, and is now an established policy of the 
 city. The Federation contains more of the wealthier classes, 
 while the Socialists and Radicals appeal to the middle classes 
 and workingmen. But an examination of the candidates for 
 the partial renewal of the municipal council in July, 1906, 
 showed how both parties appeal to all classes of the popula- 
 tion. The Federation ticket had three landed proprietors 
 out of twenty-two candidates; the "Popular" ticket had 
 two of the same class. Each ticket had four "Professors" 
 and one lawyer; and each had about six candidates from 
 the industrial classes. The Federation ticket had two mer- 
 chants and one literary man, for whom there seemed to be 
 no corresponding candidates on the opposing ticket. The 
 local campaign is very brief less than a week ; and political 
 meetings are held largely in the public schools. 
 
 It seems evident that the election of councilmen on a gen- 
 eral ticket tends to make the elections party contests, and 
 increases the influence of a well-organized party machine. 
 Few of the voters can know personally the qualifications of 
 all the twenty-two candidates for whom they will vote. The 
 Socialists have the most highly developed organization and
 
 346 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 strictest party discipline, and would probably be a more 
 powerful influence were it not for the educational and tax- 
 paying qualifications for voting, which limit the number of 
 electors. There is, however, a good deal of scratching, and 
 many mixed ballots are voted. 
 
 However exciting the campaign, there are none of the 
 corrupting influences of spoils politics. The salaried posts 
 in the municipal government of Milan, as of most Italian 
 cities, form a permanent service, recruited very largely by 
 competitive examinations. Neither the success of the "Pop- 
 ular Union" in 1900, nor of the Federation in 1904, affected 
 this service in any way. And charges of corruption or dis- 
 honesty in the municipal service are entirely unknown. 
 
 VENICE 
 
 Physical conditions in Venice are so entirely different from 
 those in other cities that at first blush it seems almost impos- 
 sible to make comparisons. But in many respects the mu- 
 nicipal problems are much the same as elsewhere, while the 
 strange features of the situation increase the interest in the 
 solution of certain problems. 
 
 Canals in Venice take the place of both streets and sewers, 
 and make necessary entirely different methods of local trans- 
 portation. The Grand Canal forms a broad thoroughfare. 
 But most of the other canals are narrow and irregularly laid 
 out, and any reconstruction of these ways of communication 
 seems out of the question. The street-paving problem is 
 greatly simplified, as the lanes for foot passengers and the 
 piazzas have no heavy traffic to bear; and these are kept 
 clean and in good condition. 
 
 A puzzling situation is presented by the use of canals for 
 sewers. Conditions would be intolerable were it not for the 
 tide, which rises and falls about three feet, and sweeping in 
 and out acts to a considerable extent as an automatic flusher. 
 In the larger canals this serves to prevent any obvious annoy- 
 ance; but in the blind ends of the smaller canals there are
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 347 
 
 distinctly objectionable odors. As the water is salt, and so 
 cannot be used for drinking, its contamination causes no 
 special danger from typhoid fever. But in other respects 
 the situation is far from satisfactory. 
 
 Gondolas take the place of cabs in Venice. They are a 
 picturesque but not a rapid means of transportation. And 
 while they will probably remain for purposes of recreation 
 and pleasure, it seems probable that for business purposes 
 they must before long give way to motor boats. A few of 
 these latter are already in use. 
 
 For some years there have been several lines of small steamers 
 operated on the Grand Canal and between the islands, as 
 the nearest approach to a street railway system. Recently 
 the city has undertaken the operation of these steamers, 
 and under municipal management the service has been 
 improved and the traffic increased. Fares are two cents 
 for any distance on the Grand Canal, and four cents across 
 the lagoon to the ocean beach at Lido. Financially, the 
 municipal system has met expenses, with a small surplus 
 for depreciation. But the service is still limited; and the 
 steamers in use can only go through the Grand Canal. An 
 extension of the service by the use of small motor boats in 
 some of the other canals is needed to make a satisfactory 
 cheap means of transportation. 
 
 The municipality also owns and operates the water supply, 
 which is brought from the mainland and piped through the 
 city. The water is good, and there is no complaint of the 
 supply or the rates. Gas, electric lights, and telephones are 
 in the hands of private companies. There has been much 
 complaint against the gas company, which has been charging 
 $1.85 per thousand cubic feet. In 1904 a special inquiry 
 was made on the gas question, and the giunta reported 
 (March, 1905) in favor of a municipal plant. But in June, 
 1906, a new franchise was granted to the company, fixing 
 the price at $1.10 per thousand cubic feet to private con- 
 sumers, and somewhat lower for public lighting. This is
 
 348 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 about the same price as the cost of gas in the municipal plant 
 at Bologna, but higher than in the municipal plants at Padua 
 and Como, and also higher than that fixed in the franchise 
 granted by the city of Rome in 1898. The latter provided 
 for a rate of $1.10 per thousand cubic feet, with gradual 
 reductions to 85 cents in 1913. The difficulties of laying 
 pipes in Venice may add somewhat to the cost and justify 
 a slightly higher rate than in other cities. 
 
 Municipal dwelling-houses are being discussed in Venice. 
 The population is badly crowded, and it is urged that the 
 city might well follow the example of Milan, and construct 
 some model houses on an unbuilt section of the island. An- 
 other project that is being mooted is the enlargement of the 
 terminal facilities, to meet the needs of increasing commerce, 
 and to prevent the loss of trade to the rival Austrian port 
 of Trieste. But no definite action has yet been taken on 
 either matter. 
 
 Local politics have been comparatively quiet in Venice. 
 The city government is controlled by the moderates or con- 
 servatives, and the present mayor has held office for ten 
 years. The Socialists are, however, becoming more active, 
 and there are several smaller and less important factions. 
 
 MUNICIPAL GAS-WORKS 
 
 None of the Italian cities that have been separately dis- 
 cussed in this article have municipal gas-works. But the 
 gas-plants have been municipalized in a number of other 
 cities, including Bologna, Leghorn, Padua, Spezzia, and Pisa, 
 among the places with over 50,000 population. The munici- 
 pal works at Spezzia date from 1877; those in the other 
 cities since 1894. 
 
 None of these works represent any very large investment 
 of capital. The largest is Bologna, where the total invest- 
 ment is $1,300,000. The 'works at Padua have cost $260,000, 
 those at Como $150,000, and the others smaller amounts. 
 All of the plants show some increase in the consumption of
 
 MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT IN ITALY 349 
 
 gas since municipalization, but the only striking cases are 
 at Padua and Como, where the consumption has more than 
 doubled in ten years. In only a few cases has it been possible 
 to learn the cost of gas at these municipal works. In Bologna, 
 the total cost, including interest and sinking-fund charges, 
 is $1.10 per thousand cubic feet; in Como it is 80 cents per 
 thousand, and in Padua 70 cents per thousand. 
 
 These results cannot be said to give a very decisive answer 
 as to the success or failure of municipalization. While the 
 cost of gas is comparatively low in two cities, that in the 
 larger city of Bologna is no less than the price made by a 
 private company in Venice, and is higher than the price now 
 charged by the private company in Rome. And, with the 
 exception of the same two cities, the consumption of gas 
 from the municipal plants in Italy is so small that the cities 
 cannot be said to be furnishing an adequate service to the 
 community, or to be doing much better than private com- 
 panies in other cities. On the other hand, the municipal 
 plants can hardly be called failures. Financially they are 
 self-sustaining, and the service is at least no worse than 
 that furnished by private companies.
 
 XIX 
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 1 
 
 AT the two preceding sessions of the National Municipal 
 League the subject of instruction in municipal government 
 has occupied an important place on the programme. Papers 
 were read at each of these meetings showing what was being 
 dpne in the colleges and universities throughout the country, 
 and urging the importance of instruction on this subject. 
 Outlines of special courses in municipal government and lists 
 of text and reference books have also been published as sug- 
 gestions for institutions which wished to add this subject 
 to their curriculum. But, as was pointed out a year ago, 
 attention has been thus far confined to the work in univer- 
 sities and colleges; and, indeed, was mainly directed toward 
 advanced courses devoted exclusively to municipal govern- 
 ment. At the last meeting of the League, however, it was 
 decided to extend the work of the committee having the matter 
 in charge to include the teaching of the principles of good 
 city government in the public and private schools. It is 
 with the subject as thus enlarged that I shall deal in this 
 paper. 
 
 Most of my time and attention will be given to those aspects 
 of the subject that have not hitherto been discussed at these 
 meetings that is, to the more elementary instruction, both 
 in schools and colleges. But I shall also say something of the 
 more advanced and specialized work in the universities; and 
 of the correlation between the instruction in different grades 
 of educational institutions. 
 
 1 Reprinted from the Proceedings of the Detroit Conference for Good 
 City Government and the Ninth Annual Meeting of the National Munici- 
 pal League (1903). 
 
 360
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 351 
 
 Let me begin by making clear the distinction between 
 the advanced special courses in municipal government such 
 as have been heretofore outlined and the more general in- 
 struction, of which I shall speak in detail first. The special 
 courses in municipal government are nowhere required courses, 
 but everywhere electives, which appeal only to a part of the 
 students in colleges and universities, principally to those 
 who specialize in political subjects. They are not taken, 
 and it is not expected that they will be taken, by the large 
 proportion of college students, whose main interests lie in 
 entirely distinct fields of study; while the much larger body 
 of future citizens who receive no college education even 
 yet more than thirty times as numerous as those who do 
 have not even the opportunity to benefit by such courses as 
 have been described. The more elementary instruction, now 
 specifically urged, is that intended for both of these classes 
 of students, to train them for the performance of their duties 
 as citizens. 
 
 It will not be necessary to take much time to show that 
 such elementary instruction is essential for the success and 
 continued progress of good city government. Our municipal 
 governments are based on a system of manhood suffrage; 
 and good municipal government depends primarily on an 
 intelligent exercise of that suffrage. The necessity for teach- 
 ing future voters the fundamental principles of American 
 government is very generally acknowledged, even where 
 the measures taken to do this work are most deficient. It 
 needs, however, to be more clearly recognized than is now 
 the case in many quarters, that the training of the future 
 voters in our cities is by no means complete with a study of 
 the national constitution, or even of the national and state 
 governments, but must also include a knowledge of that 
 government which is nearest at hand and most largely affects 
 the daily lives of the citizens, the government of the city. 
 
 Two fundamental rules may be laid down for this elemen- 
 tary instruction in municipal government, both in schools
 
 352 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 and colleges. First, if the main object of reaching the large 
 body of future voters is to be attained, the elementary in- 
 struction should not be given in a special course on munici- 
 pal government, but must be included as part of a general 
 course in government or politics, which every student should 
 be at least expected to take. Secondly, the emphasis in this 
 general instruction must be laid, not so much on the forms 
 of government, as on the functions of the officials and on the 
 rights, responsibilities, and duties of the citizens. 
 
 Of the specific nature of instruction in the elementary 
 schools I shall say but little, as a lack of experience in this 
 field leaves me incompetent to present details. It has seemed 
 to me doubtful whether systematic courses in government 
 can be taught to children below the high-school age, in a way 
 that will have much effect by the time the children reach the 
 age to exercise political duties. It is, however, possible to 
 give simple explanations of the duties and activities of those 
 public agents somewhat familiar to the children, such as the 
 policemen, school teachers, and letter-carriers. And I may 
 refer to an outline for work of this kind prepared by Mr. 
 Harry W. Thurston, of the Chicago Normal School. 
 
 In the high schools and academies, however, it is clearly 
 both possible and urgently advisable to give systematic 
 instruction in civil government, including definite work in 
 municipal government. In most of our secondary schools 
 the more general subject has already established itself; but 
 there is still need in some places for impressing on the school 
 authorities the importance of this fundamental work. Even 
 in the states of the Middle West, nearly one-sixth of the public 
 high schools give no work in civil government ; while in other 
 parts of the country the proportion of secondary schools 
 where this subject is wholly neglected is much larger, 
 from one-fourth in the North Atlantic and far Western states, 
 to one-half in the South Atlantic group. At least one city 
 of nearly 100,000 population gives no work in civil govern- 
 ment in any of the public schools.
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 353 
 
 But while some attention is given to the general subject of 
 government in most high schools, this seldom includes any- 
 thing like adequate instruction in municipal government. 
 To get some definite information as to what is now being 
 done, I sent a brief series of inquiries to the schools in fifty 
 of the most important cities in the United States. Answers 
 have been received from thirty-three of these, of which ten 
 report very little or nothing in the way of instruction in 
 municipal government; ten report somewhat more attention 
 to the subject, but still an inadequate treatment ; and thirteen 
 about one-third of the cities reporting, and only one- 
 fourth of the number of inquiries do work that may be 
 considered reasonably good. Judging from these reports, 
 the best work is that done in Boston, Cleveland, and Detroit. 
 It is surprising, however, to find some of the large cities in 
 this country still using text-books in civil government which 
 contain little or nothing more than an analysis of the national 
 constitution. One city of more than 100,000 population, 
 four hundred miles from Ohio, uses a text-book with the 
 state constitution of Ohio instead of the state in which the 
 city is located. 
 
 In view of these facts, there is an obvious need for impress- 
 ing on the school authorities in many cities the importance 
 of this subject as part of the training of the coming voters 
 in their duties and responsibilities; while the character of 
 the work done in many schools where something is attempted 
 shows the need for discussing the methods and scope of in- 
 struction, and of urging a larger attention to this subject 
 than it now receives. 
 
 Some explanation of the backward state of school instruc- 
 tion in this subject may be found in the slight attention that 
 has been given to the subject of civil government in educa- 
 tional circles. That subject has not for ten years had a place 
 on the programme of the National Educational Association. 
 The only recent discussions of the subject of any importance 
 have been in connection with plans for the teaching of history 
 
 2A
 
 354 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 in the secondary schools. And in these the teaching of civil 
 government has been emphatically subordinated to that of 
 history; while as the history work recommended ignores 
 the study of recent local government, the influence of these 
 plans has tended rather to cause the subject now before us 
 to be neglected than to secure for it the attention which 
 it merits. 
 
 The specific suggestions for high-school work in municipal 
 government that can be made in this paper are necessarily 
 brief. A preliminary step must be the abandonment of the 
 old-style manual on the national constitution as a sufficient 
 basis for work in government, and the introduction of a 
 modern text-book dealing also with state and local govern- 
 ment, and the machinery and influence of political par- 
 ties. Good books for this purpose are: James and San- 
 ford, Government in State and Nation; Ashley, The American 
 Federal State; and Bryce, The American Commonwealth, 
 abridged edition. Still better, for the study of state and 
 local government, are the text-books on the government of 
 particular states now being issued by different publishers, 
 which usually give more specific information about municipal 
 government in the state concerned than the more general 
 works can do. 1 But the most effective part of the high- 
 school course in municipal government must be that dealing 
 with the government of the city in which the school is located. 
 
 The time that can ordinarily be given to this topic in a high- 
 school course will not permit of a study of municipal govern- 
 ment in foreign countries, or even of an extended comparison 
 of municipal institutions in the different American cities. 
 But the pupils can be taught the organization and activities 
 of their own city, with a fair degree of precision; and this 
 should be the primary aim of the high-school instruction. 
 No doubt this imposes a more serious burden on the teacher, 
 requires larger training and ability, and calls for greater 
 
 1 A very useful book for the study of municipal government in schools 
 is Willard's City Government for Young People.
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 355 
 
 tact and discretion than to teach the vague generalities of 
 a text-book in use all over the country; but it is only on the 
 basis of the intensive study of their own city that satisfactory 
 work can be accomplished. An aid for this work exists in 
 many cities in the Municipal Manual, prepared for the use 
 of the city officers, copies of which can usually be secured 
 for the schools. In a few cities a small pamphlet has been 
 published on the city government, for example, in Cam- 
 bridge, Mass., and this example might be followed in all the 
 cities of importance. 
 
 Time and space do not permit of further suggestions as to 
 methods of instruction, which would, in any case, require an 
 incursion into the field of pedagogy, and may be left for dis- 
 cussion by those who have had special experience in secondary 
 education. 
 
 In our colleges and universities, too, there should be in- 
 struction in municipal government, given as part of a general 
 introductory course in government, intended not for the 
 specialized work of advanced students, but for the main body 
 of undergraduates. Some of the largest and best universities 
 in the country, which offer ample work in municipal govern- 
 ment for advanced and graduate students who specialize 
 in history and political science, fail to offer the more ele- 
 mentary work for the general body of students. The uni- 
 versities cannot be excused from this work on the ground 
 that it belongs to the secondary schools. For, on one hand, 
 as has been noted, most of our high schools do not meet this 
 need, even as far as they might ; and this lack is more apt to 
 be true of those schools whose main work is that of pre- 
 paring students for college. On the other hand, it is not too 
 much to say that every college graduate should be enabled 
 to exercise his rights of citizenship with a larger knowledge 
 and broader understanding of their significance than can be 
 given in the best secondary schools. 
 
 That part of the general college course on government 
 dealing with municipal government should differ materially
 
 356 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 from the corresponding part of the high-school course. In- 
 stead of confining attention mainly to the study of a single 
 city, the college course should include a comparative study 
 of typical American cities, with special reference to those 
 within the sphere of influence of the institution. Some 
 reference may also be made to municipal conditions in other 
 countries; but, in the main, that aspect of the subject must 
 be left to the more advanced and specialized courses. The 
 study of party machinery and the operation of extra legal 
 forces can be more exact and more definite in the college 
 than in the high-school course. And the more mature college 
 students can be taught a higher standard of ethical ideals 
 in politics than is possible with those of a younger age. 
 
 By thus emphasizing the importance of and the need for the 
 more elementary and more general instruction in municipal 
 government both in schools and colleges, I have not meant 
 to underrate the advanced specialized courses established, 
 especially in the larger universities. In view, however, of 
 the previous discussion on this phase of the subject, it will 
 not be necessary to present here any definite outline or 
 specific suggestions for such courses. But it may be worth 
 while to note the place which these courses should occupy 
 in relation to the more elementary work. While they are 
 not courses which every student can be expected to take, 
 the number of students to whom they will be of direct benefit 
 is perhaps larger than many people suppose. 
 
 In the first place, such special courses should be part of 
 the training of those who expect to become teachers of mu- 
 nicipal government as part of general courses in government 
 either in secondary schools or colleges. It is perhaps true 
 that, with a good training in history and the more general 
 aspects of political science, an exceptional teacher may be 
 able in time to develop for himself satisfactory methods and 
 plans for teaching municipal government, as has already 
 been done in some few cases. But the same advantages 
 which result from specialized training in other branches of
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 357 
 
 educational work are to be secured in this particular field; 
 and efficient and effective instruction in municipal govern- 
 ment cannot be expected to become the general rule in our 
 cities until the teachers are, for the most part, those who 
 have received such special training. 
 
 Another important class of students to whom the special 
 university courses in municipal government are of particular 
 value are those who look forward to journalism as their 
 profession. The university-trained journalist is almost 
 certain to find his lifework in one of the important cities, 
 where a large share of the subjects which will occupy his 
 time will be questions of municipal government. The 
 journalist who has given some time to a study of these ques- 
 tions from the comprehensive point of view of a university 
 course will be best prepared to discuss the problems which 
 arise in his own locality. 
 
 And in the third place, such special courses in municipal 
 government are essential for all of those who do not expect 
 their political activities to end with the ordinary duties of 
 citizens, but who anticipate a larger share in the discussion 
 and settlement of public questions and the management of 
 political affairs. It must be clearly recognized that munici- 
 pal government in our large cities, like the government at 
 Washington, will not, and indeed cannot, be intrusted to 
 citizens who, up to the time of their selection as officials, 
 have been completely engrossed in their private affairs; 
 but must be managed by men who spend much of their time 
 studying the difficult problems to be solved. Politics, even 
 under the best conditions, is no mere sport for dilettante 
 amateurs; but a serious business where professional workers 
 succeed, and must succeed, because they represent the same 
 principle of specialization of functions and division of labor 
 which lies at the base of all developing civilization. And 
 if the illiterate and dishonest hucksters who too often perform 
 this function in municipal affairs are to be driven from the 
 field, university men must prepare themselves to take their
 
 358 ESSAYS IN MUNICIPAL ADMINISTRATION 
 
 places, and to make politics as honorable a profession as any 
 other. 
 
 Besides the university courses dealing specifically with 
 municipal government as a whole, it may be worth while to 
 call attention to the opportunities which our larger univer- 
 sities offer for the more detailed study of particular branches 
 of municipal administration. These are even now being 
 constantly made use of by those who enter into the various 
 technical municipal services, as attorneys, engineers, sanitary 
 officers, school officials, and the like. But in addition to 
 this it would be possible, by combining the distinctly mu- 
 nicipal subjects in different departments of a university, to 
 present a comprehensive course in municipal administration, 
 which would be the best preliminary training for some of 
 the higher posts in municipal governments. To give a single 
 example, the office of city clerk should be a permanent one, 
 filled by a man who without having the technical training 
 of the experts in any one of the various branches of administra- 
 tion has yet had a large amount of special knowledge of 
 all of these branches. It is no doubt a somewhat fanciful 
 suggestion to propose anything of this kind in view of present 
 political conditions in this country; and I am very far from 
 urging any student to carry out such a scheme with any 
 hope of securing a suitable position. But it may be worth 
 while, at least, to call attention to the possibilities of our 
 present educational facilities, if political conditions ever 
 become such as to utilize these advantages. 
 
 In conclusion, I have attempted to suggest in this paper 
 a correlated scheme of instruction in municipal government 
 running through the whole educational system, which may 
 be roughly summarized as follows : 
 
 1. Simple lessons in the duties of public agents in the 
 elementary schools. 
 
 2. The systematic study .of one city in high schools and 
 academies. 
 
 3. A comparative study of American municipal govern-
 
 INSTRUCTION IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT 359 
 
 ment as part of a general course in government in all our 
 colleges and universities. 
 
 4. A comprehensive study of municipal government for 
 advanced students in the universities, leading to, 
 
 5. The technical courses in the various professional de- 
 partments of the universities.
 
 INDEX 
 
 Accounting, system of, in New York 
 City, 185-186; in Philadelphia, 194; 
 completeness and uniformity in, 
 demanded under public ownership, 
 268-269, 274, 285 ; in Italian cities, 
 333. 
 
 Administrative control of municipal 
 officials, 33-37. 
 
 Agamenticus, a colonial borough, 
 50 n., 51 ; aldermen in, 70, 71. 
 
 Akron, O., statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Albany, N.Y., a colonial borough 
 (1686), 50 n., 60, 61, 63 ff . ; Don- 
 gan's charter of incorporation for, 
 54; statistics of present council of, 
 141 ; commissioner of public works 
 in, 169. 
 
 Aldermen, in colonial boroughs, 70- 
 71, 76; election and compensation 
 of, in New York and Boston, 132, 
 133. 
 
 Allegheny, Pa., mode of election to 
 council, 129 ; statistics of council, 
 140 ; director of public works in, 169. 
 
 Allen law, in Illinois, 238. 
 
 Allentown, Pa., council of, 142. 
 
 Allinson, cited, 55, 65, 68, 74, 76, 78, 
 80, 81, 83, 84, 85, 87, 91. 
 
 Altgeld, Governor, 238. 
 
 Altoona, Pa., council of, 142. 
 
 Anderson, Ind., 119; state-appointed 
 police board in, 149. 
 
 Annapolis, a colonial borough (1708), 
 50 n., 56, 62, 65 ff. 
 
 Ann Arbor, municipal expenses of, 5. 
 
 Annuaire Statistique, France, 277. 
 
 Annuario Statistico Italiano, 277. 
 
 Aqueduct board, New York State, 166. 
 
 Arizona, rangers in, 148. 
 
 Arkansas, regulation of water, gas, 
 and electricity rates in cities of, 162. 
 
 Arnold, Bion J., 253, 260. 
 
 Ashley, W. J., 296 ; American Federal 
 State by, as a text-book, 354. 
 
 Asphalt plant, municipal, in Detroit, 
 150. 
 
 Assessing officers, administrative su- 
 pervision of, 35. 
 
 Assessment, rotation in, in Toronto, 
 204-205. 
 
 Assessments, revenue from special, in 
 New York City, 187; in Philadel- 
 phia, 192-193, 195; in St. Louis, 
 196, 199; in Boston, 202; in 
 Toronto, 206; in European coun- 
 tries, 216. 
 
 "Assessments" in Scotland, 212. 
 
 Atchison, municipal waterworks au- 
 thorized in, 155. 
 
 Atkinson, cited, 206. 
 
 Atlanta, bicameral council in, 126 ; 
 statistics of council, 141 . 
 
 Atlantic City, N.J., council of, 143. 
 
 Auburn, N.Y., council of, 143. 
 
 Auditing of revenue and expense, in 
 New York City, 185-186 ; in Phila- 
 delphia, 194. 
 
 Auditor, office of municipal, in Ohio, 
 105. 
 
 Augusta, Ga., council of, 142. 
 
 Austria, municipal conditions in, 316- 
 317. 
 
 Baltimore, incorporated as a city 
 (1787), 59; bicameral council in, 
 126 ; mode of election to council in, 
 129 ; pay of members of council, 
 133 ; statistics of council, 140 ; state- 
 appointed police board in, 148 ; re- 
 construction of, after fire of 1904, 
 151 ; administration of public works 
 in, 168. 
 
 Bank deposits, public, in New York, 
 187. 
 
 Bank shares, taxation of, in New 
 York, 186. 
 
 Bath, N.C., a colonial borough, 50 n., 
 56. 
 
 Baths, superintendent of, in borough 
 of Manhattan, 165; public, in 
 Scotland, 288; in Munich, 312; in 
 Budapest, 314 ; in Vienna, 323. 
 
 Bay City, Mich., statistics of council, 
 143. 
 
 Bayonne, N.J., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 361
 
 362 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Bellmen in colonial boroughs, 87. 
 
 Berlin, Germany, tabular statement 
 of finances of, 175-179; revenue 
 system of, 210, 214-215, 216 ff . ; 
 municipal ownership in, 216 ; local 
 transportation in, 303-308. 
 
 Berlin, N.H., state-appointed police 
 board in, 149. 
 
 Bermuda Hundred, Va., a colonial 
 borough, 50. 
 
 BUanci Comunali, Italy, 277. 
 
 Binghamton, N.Y., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 142. 
 
 Birmingham, Ala., term of service in 
 council in, 128; appointing power 
 of council in, 138 ; statistics of 
 council, 142; state-appointed police 
 board, 148. 
 
 Birmingham, Eng., municipal enter- 
 prises in, 292-296. 
 
 Bishop, C. F., cited, 64, 66. 
 
 Black, cited, 89. 
 
 Blair v. Chicago, case of, cited, 233, 
 252. 
 
 Boards of health. See Health. 
 
 Bolting Act, in New York, 61. 
 
 Borough, the English, 48-50. 
 
 Boroughs, colonial, in America, 50 ff . ; 
 charters for, 52 ff . ; opposition to 
 system of, 58; so-called cities the 
 same institution as, 58; signifi- 
 cance of location of, 5859 ; status 
 of citizens in, 60-62 ; the suffrage 
 in, 62-67 ; organization of, 67-75 ; 
 mayor, 68-69, 76; recorder, 69-70, 
 76; aldermen, 70-71, 76; council- 
 men, 71-72; other charter officials, 
 72-73 ; wards in, 74 ; town meetings 
 in, 7475 ; judicial functions in, 
 75-77 ; legislative functions, 77-79 ; 
 markets and fairs in, 79-80 ; ferries 
 in, 81-82; docks and wharves in, 
 82; streets and roads in, 82-84; 
 water supply, 8485; fire-engines 
 in, 85-86 ; police in, 86-88 ; finances 
 of, 88-94. 
 
 Boston, mayor's power of nomination 
 in, 22 ; competitive examinations 
 for filling municipal positions in, 26 ; 
 receives a city charter (1822), 59 n. ; 
 bicameral council in, 126 ; number 
 of members of council in, 127 ; mode 
 of election to council in, 129; mi- 
 nority-representation voting scheme 
 in, 132; pay of members of -board 
 of aldermen, 133; pay of members 
 of common council, 134; statistics 
 of council, 140; state-appointed 
 police board in, 148; single police 
 
 commissioner and excise board in 
 (1906), 149; subways in, 154-155; 
 regulation of price of gas in, 161- 
 162 ; administration of public works 
 in, 167-168; tabular statement of 
 finances of, 174-180; revenue sys- 
 tem of, 200-203; instruction in 
 municipal government in, 353. 
 
 Bridgeport, Conn., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 141. 
 
 Bristol, Pa., a colonial borough, 50 n. ; 
 charter of, 55. 
 
 Brockton, Mass., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Brooks, R. C., cited, 207. 
 
 Bryce, James, on American municipal 
 government, 5 ; mistake of, concern- 
 ing bicameral councils, 126 n. ; 
 American Commonwealth as a text- 
 book, 354. 
 
 Budapest, municipal conditions in, 
 312-315; comparison between St. 
 Louis and, 313. 
 
 Buffalo, bicameral council in, 126; 
 term of service in council, 127 ; mode 
 of election to council, 129 ; pay of 
 members of council, 133; statistics 
 of council, 140; administration of 
 public works in, 170; electric 
 lighting figures in, compared with 
 Detroit, 227. 
 
 Burgesses, House of, Virginia, 51, 65. 
 
 Burgomaster, position of, in Vienna, 
 319 ; Karl Lueger as, 321-323. 
 
 Burial-grounds, public, in Scotland, 
 288. 
 
 Burlington, N.J., a colonial borough, 
 50 n., 57, 65 ff. 
 
 Bushnell, Governor, of Ohio, 115. 
 
 Business assessment, Toronto, 204. 
 
 Busse, Mayor F. A., 257. 
 
 Butte, Mont., statistics of council, 143. 
 
 C 
 
 Cable traction, establishment of, in 
 Chicago, 236. 
 
 Cab traffic, in London, 296-297; in 
 Berlin, 307. 
 
 Cabs (cabriolets), in Naples, 335. 
 
 California, home-rule charters in, 31 ; 
 municipal ownership in, 156; fran- 
 chise law (1901), 158. 
 
 Cambridge, Mass., independent politi- 
 cal organization in, 8; statistics 
 of council, 141 ; administration of 
 public works in, 171 ; pamphlet on 
 the city government published in, 
 355.
 
 INDEX 
 
 363 
 
 Camden, N.J., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Canton, O., statistics of council, 143. 
 
 Cedar Rapids, la., statistics of council, 
 143. 
 
 Census statistics in United States, 
 282-285. 
 
 Chamberlain, office of, in colonial 
 boroughs, 72-73. 
 
 Chamberlain, Joseph, 292. 
 
 Charitable institutions, 4. 
 
 Charity and correction, state boards 
 of, 35. 
 
 Charleston, incorporated as city (1783), 
 59 ; term of service in council, 128 ; 
 statistics of council, 141. 
 
 Charters, city, 28; home-rule, 31-32; 
 New York's as colonial borough 
 or corporation, 52-54; of Albany, 
 Philadelphia, and other boroughs, 
 54-58; of Charleston, Baltimore, 
 Boston, and other cities, 59-60; 
 stream of municipal, after Revo- 
 lution, 59-60. 
 
 Chattanooga, bicameral council in, 
 126 ; statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Chelsea, Mass., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Chester, Pa., a colonial borough, 50; 
 charter of, 56; statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Chicago, Municipal Voters' League in, 
 9, 238, 239, 249; council's power 
 to establish offices in, 18; adminis- 
 trative powers of council in, 18 ; 
 position of mayor in, 21 ; mayor's 
 power of nomination, 22 ; com- 
 petitive examinations in, 26; term 
 of office of mayor of, 112 n. ; office 
 of corporation counsel in, 113; dis- 
 advantages to, from limitation on 
 financial powers and multiplication 
 of authorities, 114; failure to carry 
 proposed new charter for, 114 n. ; 
 single-chamber council in, 126 ; 
 number of members of council in, 
 127 ; statistics of council, 128, 129, 
 133, 140; election of sanitary 
 trustees in, 132; mayor's nomina- 
 tions to offices in, confirmed by 
 council, 138; ordinances of, 139; 
 Drainage Canal, 152; legislative 
 acts regarding parks for, 152; mu- 
 nicipal street railway question in, 
 157, 162, 230-259; administration 
 of public works in, 166; tabular 
 statement of finances of, 174-180 ; 
 revenues of, compared with other 
 cities, 180-181 ; expenditures of, 
 
 compared with European cities, 
 217-218 ; comparison between street 
 railway equipment of Munich and, 
 312; comparison between Milan 
 and, 340. 
 
 Chicago City Railway Company, 232, 
 233, 247, 253, 258. 
 
 Chicago Passenger Railway Company, 
 236. 
 
 Chicago Railways Company, 255. 
 
 Chicago Union Traction Company, 239, 
 246, 253. 
 
 Chicago West Division Railway Com- 
 pany, 232, 237. 
 
 Christian Socialists, Vienna, 321-323. 
 
 Cincinnati, single-chamber council in, 
 126; service in council, mode of 
 election, and other statistics, 128, 
 129, 140; control of police in, 149; 
 water-supply system for, 153; ad- 
 ministration of public works in, 169. 
 
 Cities, in ancient times, 1 ; decline of, 
 with decline of Roman Empire, 1 ; 
 growth of, in number and size in 
 18th century, 1-2; increase of, in 
 19th century, 2 ; increasing im- 
 portance of government of, 2-3 ; 
 duties and activities of government 
 of, 35 ; expenditures on municipal 
 institutions in, 5 ; official corruption 
 in, 6; defects in government of, 
 6-7 ; causes and remedies of, 7-10 ; 
 relation between state and, 2638; 
 classification of, 29, 111, 114, 119- 
 120; attempts to prohibit special 
 legislation for, 29-32, 111, 114-115; 
 charters of, 31 ; origins of American, 
 in chartered boroughs or municipal 
 corporations, 48 (see Boroughs) ; 
 government in Italian, 330-333; 
 instruction in government of, 350- 
 359. 
 
 Citizens, status of, in colonial bor- 
 oughs, 60-67. 
 
 Citizens' Association, Chicago, 235. 
 
 City attorneys in Illinois, 113. 
 
 City clerk, appointment to office of, 
 137-138; in Italian cities called 
 secretary-general, 331. 
 
 City clerks in Illinois, 113. 
 
 City engineer in New York cities, 169. 
 
 City treasurers in Illinois, 113. 
 
 Civic Federation, Chicago, 240. 
 
 Civil service in Milan, 346. 
 
 Civil service rules in cities, 26, 39-47. 
 
 Classification of cities, 29, 111; in 
 Ohio, 114; in Indiana, 119-120. 
 
 Cleveland, mayor's power of nomina- 
 tion in (1891-1903), 22; so-called
 
 364 
 
 INDEX 
 
 "federal plan" of, mentioned, 25; 
 legislative acts of 1902 affecting, 
 99-101 ; single-chamber council in, 
 126; service in council in, 128; 
 mode of election to council in, 129 ; 
 mayor's nominations to offices in, 
 confirmed by council, 138 ; statistics 
 of council, 140 ; instruction in mu- 
 nicipal government in, 353. 
 
 Colorado, home-rule charters in, 31 ; 
 granting of franchises in (1905), 161. 
 
 Columbus, O., statistics of council, 140. 
 
 Commerce and Labor, Department of, 
 283-284. 
 
 Committees of municipal councils, 
 135-136. 
 
 Como, municipal gas-works in, 349. 
 
 Compensation. See Pay. 
 
 Comptroller, office of, in New York 
 City, 183-184. 
 
 Connecticut, early incorporation of 
 cities in, 59; state police in, 147- 
 148. 
 
 Cooley, Mortimer E., 253. 
 
 Corporation counsels in Illinois cities, 
 113. 
 
 Corporation taxes, Pennsylvania, 194 
 195. 
 
 Corporations, municipal, in colonial 
 America, 48 ff. 
 
 Corruption, official, 6 ; apparent free- 
 dom from, in Vienna, 329 ; unknown 
 in Milan, 346. 
 
 Council Bluffs, la., statistics of 
 council, 143. 
 
 Councilmen in colonial boroughs, 71- 
 72. 
 
 Councils, municipal, 12 ; composition 
 of, election to, and compensation 
 of members, 13; criticism of these 
 elements of organization, 14 ; plan 
 of National Municipal League, 14 
 15 ; scope and methods of action of, 
 16 ff. ; legislative and administra- 
 tive powers of, 17-20; in colonial 
 boroughs, 71-72; office of president 
 of, in Ohio, 105 ; under new mu- 
 nicipal code in Ohio, 105, 107, 115- 
 116, 117; of Illinois cities, 112; in 
 Indiana cities, 120; number of 
 chambers of, 126 ; number of mem- 
 bers of, 126-127; term of service 
 in, 127-128; mode of election to, 
 129-131 ; minority representation 
 in, 131-133 ; compensation of mem- 
 bers of, 133-134; business standing 
 and character of members, 134-135 ; 
 times of meeting, and presiding 
 officers, 135; committees of, 135- 
 
 136; control over administrative 
 officers by, 136-139 ; power of 
 enacting ordinances, 139140 ; sta- 
 tistics of, of American cities, 140 
 141; in Italian cities, 331. 
 
 County Council, London, 207-208; 
 tramways owned and operated by, 
 298. 
 
 Courts, control of municipal officials 
 by, 32-33; in colonial boroughs, 
 76-77. 
 
 Covington, Ky., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Cumulative voting, 133. 
 
 D 
 
 Dallas, Texas, members-at-large of 
 council of, 131 ; statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Dalrymple, manager municipal tram- 
 ways, Glasgow, 249 n. 
 
 Darrow, Clarence S., 252; article by, 
 cited, 261. 
 
 Davenport, la., council of, 142. 
 
 Dayton, O., council of, 141. 
 
 Debt, of New York City, 188; of 
 Philadelphia, 194; Boston, 201- 
 202; Toronto, 206. 
 
 Debt limit in Indiana cities, 123. 
 
 Debt limits, 272-273. 
 
 Debts and assets of five American 
 and five European cities, 179. 
 
 Denver, home-rule charter of, 32 ; 
 pay of members of council, 133 ; 
 statistics of council, 140; control 
 of police in, 149. 
 
 Des Moines, la., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Detroit, publicity secured to legislative 
 bills affecting, 30 ; single-chamber 
 council in, 126 ; membership of 
 council in, 128 ; mode of election to 
 council in, 129 ; pay of members 
 of council, 133; list of council 
 committees, 136 n. ; statistics of 
 council, 140 ; municipal asphalt 
 plant in, 150 ; administration of 
 public works in, 171 ; municipal 
 electric lighting in, 219-229, 271; 
 instruction in municipal govern- 
 ment in, 353. 
 
 Dillon, Judge, cited, 27 ; quoted, 136- 
 137. 
 
 Docks, in colonial boroughs, 82 ; super- 
 vision of, in New York City, 165, 
 166; revenue from, in New York 
 City, 187; municipal, in Scotland, 
 287.
 
 INDEX 
 
 365 
 
 Drainage Canal, Chicago, 152. 
 
 Drainage systems, 4. 
 
 Dubuque, la., statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Duluth, Minn., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Dunne, Mayor E. F., 248-249, 252, 
 256, 257 ; cited, 260. 
 
 Du Pont, A. B., 253. 
 
 Durand, E. D., cited, 90, 189. 
 
 Dwellings, public working-class, in 
 Scotland, 288 ; working-class, in 
 Birmingham, England, 294-296 ; 
 in Vienna, 328; working-class, in 
 Milan, 343-344; discussion of sub- 
 ject of municipal, in Venice, 348. 
 
 E 
 
 Easton, Pa., council of, 143. 
 
 East River Bridge commission, 165. 
 
 East St. Louis, council of, 143. 
 
 Education, boards of, in Cook County, 
 111., 113. 
 
 Election to councils, 129-131. 
 
 Elections, date of, in Ohio, 118; in 
 Indiana, 119. 
 
 Electric lighting, municipal control of 
 rates, 161-162; municipal, in De- 
 troit, 219-229. 
 
 Electric lighting plants, municipal, 4, 
 107, 153-154, 219-229; under new 
 Ohio code, 155. 
 
 Electric light systems, franchises for, 
 159-163. 
 
 Electric railways, underground, in 
 London, 299. 
 
 Electricity works, municipal, in Scot- 
 land, 287 ; municipal and company, 
 in London, 300302 ; in Leipzig, 
 309; in Munich, 311; municipal, 
 in Vienna, 323, 325-326. 
 
 Elizabeth, N.J., a colonial borough, 
 50 n., 60, 61, 65 ff. ; charter of, 57 ; 
 statistics of council, 141. 
 
 Elkhart, Ind., state-appointed police 
 board in, 149. 
 
 Ellis, Wade H., cited, 115. 
 
 Elmira, N.Y., council of, 142. 
 
 Emery, G. A., cited, 51. 
 
 Employment offices, New York City, 
 184. 
 
 England, municipal statistics in, 275- 
 277 ; municipal activities in, 292- 
 302. See London. 
 
 Erie, Pa., statistics of council, 141. 
 
 Estimate, boards of, in five New 
 York cities, 126. 
 
 Evansville, Ind., 119; term of ser- 
 
 vice in council, 128; statistics of 
 council, 141. 
 
 Examinations, competitive, for filling 
 municipal positions, 26. 
 
 Expenditures, comparison of Ameri- 
 can and European municipal, 176 
 179, 217-218. 
 
 Factory inspection, 147. 
 
 Fairs in colonial boroughs, 7980. 
 
 Fall River, statistics of council, 141 ; 
 state-appointed police board in, 148. 
 
 Ferries, in colonial boroughs (New 
 York, Albany, Philadelphia, Bris- 
 tol, and Burlington), 81-82; super- 
 vision of, in New York City, 165, 
 166. 
 
 Fines for refusal to accept office in 
 colonial boroughs, 73. 
 
 Fire departments, 3, 40; in colonial 
 boroughs, 85-86. 
 
 Fisher, Walter L., 243, 252. 
 
 Fiske, John, cited, 56 n. 
 
 Fitchburg, Mass., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 142. 
 
 Florence, municipal conditions in, 
 338-340. 
 
 Ford, H. J., cited, 23. 
 
 Foreman, Milton J., 241, 249. 
 
 Fort Wayne, Ind., 119; statistics of 
 council, 142. 
 
 Fort Worth, Texas, appointing power 
 of council in, 138; statistics of 
 council, 143. 
 
 France, municipal statistics in, 277. 
 
 Franchises, under Indiana municipal 
 law, 123 ; and public control, 158 
 163 ; street railway, in Chicago, 
 231 ff . ; disposition of existing, 
 when municipal ownership is in- 
 troduced, 272 ; present tendency 
 to short-term, in United States, 
 273-274. 
 
 Franklin Parmalee & Co., 231. 
 
 Freemen in colonial boroughs, 60-62. 
 
 G 
 
 Gage, Governor, of California, 31. 
 
 Galveston, plan of municipal organiza- 
 tion in, 13 n. ; membership of com- 
 mission exercising powers of council 
 in, 127 ; statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Garbage disposal, 150. 
 
 Gardiner, H. B., cited, 283 n. 
 
 Gas, regulation of price of, in New 
 York and Boston, 161-162.
 
 366 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Gas companies, revenues derived from, 
 188, 192; revenue from, in Paris, 
 216. 
 
 Gas systems, franchises for, 159163. 
 
 Gas-works, municipal, 154 ; in Scot- 
 land, 287; in Birmingham, Eng., 
 292; in Leipzig, 309; in Munich, 
 311; in Vienna, 323, 324-325; in 
 Bologna and other Italian cities, 
 332, 348-349; private, in Venice, 
 347. 
 
 General property tax, New York City, 
 186; Philadelphia, 190, 194; St. 
 Louis, 196; Boston, 202; Toronto, 
 204. 
 
 Georgeana, city of (Agamenticus), 51. 
 
 Germantown, Pa., a colonial borough 
 (1687), 50 n. ; charter of, 55. 
 
 Germany, municipal undertakings in, 
 4, 271272; dwelling-house laws 
 in, 150. See Berlin. 
 
 Glasgow, tabular statement of finances 
 of, 175-179 ; revenue system of, 
 211, 212-213, 216 ff . ; municipal 
 telephone system in, 287, 290-292; 
 tramways in, 288-290. 
 
 Gloucester, Mass., statistics of council, 
 143. 
 
 Goodwin, George B., cited, 231, 261. 
 
 Gorges, Sir Fernando, 51. 
 
 Grand Rapids, position of mayor in, 
 21 ; statistics of council, 141 ; grant- 
 ing of franchises in, 160; board of 
 public works in, 171. 
 
 Gray, J. H., cited, 238, 261. 
 
 Great Britain, municipal ownership 
 in, 4, 271-272, 287-292. See Eng- 
 land and Scotland. 
 
 Grosscup decision, 247. 
 
 H 
 
 Harbor works, municipal, in Scotland, 
 
 287. 
 
 Harding, George F., 235. 
 Harlan, John M., 240, 243, 248, 253. 
 Harrisburg, Pa., council of, 141. 
 Harrison, Mayor Carter, Jr., 238-239, 
 
 241 n., 243, 248 ; cited, 260. 
 Hartford, made a city (1784), 59; 
 
 statistics of council, 141. 
 Haverhill, Mass., council of, 142. 
 Hazard, cited, 51, 70. 
 Health, boards of, 3, 34-35, 40; in 
 
 Ohio, 106; in Cook County, HI., 
 
 113. 
 Hening, cited, 56, 57, 65, 71, 76, 77, 
 
 87, 92, 93. 
 Henrico, Va., a colonial borough, 50. 
 
 Hoboken, N.J., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Holcomb, W. P., cited, 55, 75, 80, 82, 
 92. 
 
 Holyoke, Mass., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Home-rule charters, 31. 
 
 Hooker, George E., cited, 261. 
 
 Hospitals, municipal, 4 ; in New York 
 City, 152 ; in Budapest, 314. 
 
 Housing of working classes, in Glas- 
 gow, 288; in Birmingham, Eng., 
 294-296 ; in Vienna, 328 ; in Milan, 
 343-344 ; in Venice, 348. 
 
 Houston, plan of municipal organiza- 
 tion in, 13 n. ; commission exercis- 
 ing powers of council in, 127 n., 
 142. 
 
 Howe, F. C., cited, 68, 262. 
 
 Hudson, N.Y., incorporated, 59. 
 
 Hugo, C., cited, 150. 
 
 Humphrey Bills, Illinois, 238. 
 
 Huntington, Ind., state-appointed 
 police board in, 149. 
 
 Hutchinson, Thomas, cited, 59 n. 
 
 Illinois, municipal corporation act of, 
 18, 19 ; powers of mayors in, 22 ; 
 legislative interference in municipal 
 government in, 28; special legis- 
 lation in, limited by law of 1872, 28 ; 
 Cities and Villages Act in, 111-114; 
 council, mayor and other officers, 
 system of finances, and multiplica- 
 tion of authorities in cities of, 112 
 114 ; power of city councils to create 
 local offices, 137 ; municipal street 
 railways authorized in, 156157; 
 street railway provisions in con- 
 stitution of, 235. See Chicago. 
 
 Independent political organizations, 
 8-9. 
 
 Indiana, mayors' power of nomination 
 in, 22; municipal "cabinets" in, 
 25 ; scope of legislative powers in 
 relation to cities in, 27 ; municipal 
 law in, 118-124; members-at-large 
 of councils of cities in, 131 ; mu- 
 nicipal code in (1905), 146; state- 
 appointed police boards in cities of, 
 149; municipal ownership in, 157; 
 granting of franchises in, 161. 
 
 Indianapolis, 119; council of, 140. 
 
 Ingle, E., cited, 57, 65. 
 
 Injunctions, 32. 
 
 Instruction in city government, 350- 
 359.
 
 INDEX 
 
 367 
 
 Insurance premiums (fire), state tax 
 on, in Pennsylvania, 192 n. 
 
 International Congress of Statistics, 
 278. 
 
 Iowa, municipal methods in, 13 n. ; 
 "commission plan" in, 117 n., 
 127 n. ; number of members of 
 councils in cities in, 127 ; members- 
 at-large of councils of cities in, 131 ; 
 municipal waterworks in, 158. 
 
 Italy, municipal statistics in, 277- 
 278 ; municipal government in, 330- 
 349. See Milan, Naples, etc. 
 
 Jackson, Mich., council of, 143. 
 
 Jacksonville, Fla., council of, 143. 
 
 Jamestown, Va., a colonial borough, 
 50. 
 
 Jeffersonville, Ind., state-appointed 
 police board in, 149. 
 
 Jersey City, council of, 134, 140. 
 
 Jews in Vienna, 321-322, 329. 
 
 Johnstown, Pa., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Joliet, 111., statistics of council, 143. 
 
 Journalists, courses in municipal gov- 
 ernment of advantage to, 357. 
 
 Judicial control of municipal officials, 
 32-33. 
 
 Judson, F. N., cited, 199. 
 
 Kansas, municipal methods in, 13 n. ; 
 "commission plan" in, 117 n., 
 127 n. ; municipal ownership in, 
 155; franchise act of 1903, 160; 
 granting of franchises in (1905), 161. 
 
 Kansas City, Mo., home-rule charter 
 of, 31 ; council of, 140 ; state- 
 appointed police board in, 148. 
 
 Kansas City, Kan., statistics of 
 council, 141. 
 
 Keene, N.H., state-appointed police 
 board in, 149. 
 
 Kent, J., cited, 80, 81. 
 
 Kentucky, bicameral council in cities 
 of, 126. 
 
 Kittery, a colonial borough, 50 n., 51. 
 
 Knoxville, Term., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 142. 
 
 Korosi, Josef, 278. 
 
 Labor, Commissioner of, 283. 
 
 La Crosse, Wis., council of, 128, 143. 
 
 La Fayette, Ind., state-appointed 
 
 police board in, 149. 
 Lancaster, Pa., a colonial borough, 
 
 50 n., 64; charter of, 56; council 
 
 of, 142. 
 Lawrence, Mass., statistics of council, 
 
 141. 
 Leavenworth, municipal waterworks 
 
 authorized in, 155. 
 
 Leghorn, municipal gas-works in, 348. 
 Legislation, special, for cities, 28-29, 
 
 110-111, 114-115. 
 Legislatures, powers of, regarding 
 
 cities, 27-32. 
 Leipzig, municipal conditions in, 308- 
 
 309. 
 Lexington, Ky., statistics of council, 
 
 143. 
 
 Libraries, public, 4, 6-7. 
 Library board in Cook County, 111., 
 
 113. 
 License revenue, New York City, 187; 
 
 Philadelphia, 191; St. Louis, 198; 
 
 Boston, 203; Toronto, 205. 
 Lighting plants, municipal, 4, 107, 
 
 153-154, 155, 219-229. 
 Lincoln, Neb., statistics of council, 142. 
 Liquor licenses, municipal, 184, 187, 
 
 191, 198, 203, 205. 
 
 Little Rock, Ark., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 142. 
 
 Local Taxation Returns, England, 275. 
 Logansport, Ind., state-appointed po- 
 lice board in, 149. 
 London, tabular statement of finances 
 
 of, 175-179; revenue system of, 
 
 207-209, 211-213, 215, 216 ff . ; 
 
 municipal ownership in, 216-217; 
 
 local transportation question in, 
 
 296-300. 
 London county council, 207-208; 
 
 tramways owned and operated by, 
 
 298. 
 
 Lorimer, William C., 243. 
 Los Angeles, statistics of council, 133, 
 
 141. 
 Louisville, members of council not 
 
 paid, 134 ; statistics of council, 140. 
 Low, Seth, 186. 
 
 Lowell, Mass., statistics of council, 141. 
 Lueger, Karl, 321, 322-323. 
 Lynn, Mass., statistics of council, 141. 
 
 M 
 
 Macaulay, T. B., cited, 49. 
 McKeesport, Pa., council of, 142. 
 Maiden, Mass., council of, 142. 
 Maltbie, M. R., cited, 240.
 
 368 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Manchester, N.H., council of, 141 ; 
 state-appointed police board in, 148. 
 
 Markets, in colonial boroughs, 79-80; 
 municipal, in Scotland, 287 ; in 
 Leipzig, 309; in Munich, 311; in 
 Vienna, 323. 
 
 Massachusetts, legislative interfer- 
 ence in municipal government in, 
 28; early towns of, as corporate 
 bodies, 59 n. ; state police force in, 
 147. 
 
 Matthews, Nathan, statistics by, 134- 
 135. 
 
 Mayor, 12, 13; veto power of, over 
 legislative acts of council, 18 ; 
 pedigree of the word and position of 
 modern officer, 20-21 ; election and 
 payment of, 21 ; duties and powers 
 of, 21-23 ; in colonial boroughs, 
 68-69, 76; in Ohio cities, 105-106, 
 116; position of, in Illinois cities, 
 112-113; of Chicago, 112 n.; under 
 Indiana law, 120-121, 124. 
 
 Mechem, cited, 39 n. 
 
 Memphis, council of, 127, 128, 141; 
 municipal waterworks in, 152. 
 
 Mercantile license tax, Philadelphia, 
 190-191. 
 
 Merchants' and manufacturers' special 
 tax and license, St. Louis, 197-198. 
 
 Merit system applied to municipal 
 officials, 43-47, 117-118; in Indi- 
 ana, 124. 
 
 Merriam, C. E., collaborator on essay, 
 173. 
 
 Meyer, H. R., work by, 262. 
 
 Michigan, legislative power of city 
 councils in, 19 n. ; scope of legis- 
 lative powers in relation to cities 
 in, 27 ; legislative interference in 
 municipal government in, 28; cu- 
 mulative voting held unconstitu- 
 tional in, 133 n. ; maximum pro- 
 portion of municipal lighting plants 
 in, 154. 
 
 Middletown, Conn., made a city, 59. 
 
 Milan, municipal government in, 340- 
 346. 
 
 Mill, J. S., quoted, 36. 
 
 Milwaukee, single-chamber council 
 in, 126 ; statistics of council, 140 ; 
 administration of public works in, 
 170. 
 
 Minneapolis, charter of, 32; appoint- 
 ing power of council in, 138; sta- 
 tistics of council, 140. 
 
 Minnesota, home-rule charters in, 31 ; 
 franchises for water supply and 
 lighting in, 160. 
 
 Minority-representation schemes of 
 voting, 131-133. 
 
 Mississippi, municipal control of water 
 and lighting rates in, 162. 
 
 Missouri, legislative interference in 
 municipal government in, 28; mu- 
 nicipal ownership in, 155 ; mu- 
 nicipal waterworks in, 158 ; regula- 
 tion of water, gas, electricity, and 
 telephone rates in cities of, 162. 
 
 Mobile, bicameral council in, 126; 
 term of service in council of, 128; 
 statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Montana, referendum on franchises 
 in, 160. 
 
 Montgomery, Ala., council of, 131, 
 138, 143. 
 
 Moore, cited, 56. 
 
 Mortgages, tax on, New York City, 
 189. 
 
 Muller, Senator, 243. 
 
 Miiller Law, the, 243-247, 250. 
 
 Munich, municipal conditions in, 309- 
 312. 
 
 Muncie, Ind., 119; state-appointed 
 police board in, 149. 
 
 Municipal code of Ohio, 105-109. 
 
 Municipal industries, revenue from, 
 in New York City, 187; Philadel- 
 phia, 191-192; St. Louis, 198; 
 Boston, 203; Toronto, 205. 
 
 Municipal ownership, in Indiana cities, 
 123 ; recent legislation concerning, 
 152-158; in European cities, 216- 
 217, 287-302, 303 ff. ; electric 
 lighting in Detroit, 219-229; of 
 Chicago street railways, 241-259; 
 Address on, 262-274 ; need of com- 
 plete and uniform system of ac- 
 counting under, 268, 274; in Scot- 
 land, 287-292; in Birmingham, 
 292-296; in London, 296-302; in 
 Vienna, 323-329; of gas-works in 
 Italian cities, 332, 348-349; of 
 street railways in Milan, 341-343. 
 
 Municipal-service revenue in Euro- 
 pean cities, 216-217. 
 
 Municipal Voters' League, Chicago, 
 9, 238, 239, 249. 
 
 Munsell, J., cited, 54, 63, 64, 66, 67, 69, 
 73, 78, 79, 83, 86, 87, 88, 91, 93. 
 
 Murray, N., cited, 68, 74, 77. 
 
 Museums, municipal, 4; in Rome, 
 337-338. 
 
 N 
 
 Naples, municipal conditions in, 333- 
 336.
 
 INDEX 
 
 369 
 
 Nashville, method of publishing city 
 ordinances, 139-140; statistics of 
 council, 141. 
 
 National Municipal League, municipal 
 program adopted by, 12 ; provisions 
 of plan, 14, 19, 22-23, 25; instruc- 
 tion in municipal government in 
 program of, 350. 
 
 Neefe, M., 279. 
 
 Nettlefold, Mr., 295-296. 
 
 New Albany, Ind., 119; state-ap- 
 pointed police board in, 149. 
 
 Newark, N.J., statistics of council, 
 128, 134, 140; administration of 
 public works in, 170. 
 
 New Bedford, Mass., council of, 141. 
 
 New Britain, Conn., council of, 143. 
 
 New Brunswick, N.J., a colonial 
 borough, 50 n. ; charter of, 57. 
 
 Newcastle, Pa., statistics of council, 
 143. 
 
 New Haven, Conn., made a city, 59; 
 council of, 140. 
 
 New Jersey, colonial boroughs in, 50, 
 57-58, 64 ff. ; incorporation of cities 
 in, 59 ; law affecting cities in, 146 ; 
 state police in, 147 ; sewerage system 
 in, 152 ; municipal ownership in, 
 157-158; granting of franchises in, 
 160. 
 
 New London, Conn., created a city, 59. 
 
 New Mexico, mounted police in, 148. 
 
 New Orleans, competitive examina- 
 tions for filling municipal positions 
 in, 26; council of, 126, 127, 140; 
 police administration in, 149 ; un- 
 derground sewer construction in, 
 151. 
 
 Newport, Ky., statistics of council, 143. 
 
 Newport, R.I., incorporated as city 
 (1784), 59; state police board pro- 
 vided for, 149. 
 
 Newton, Mass., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 New York City, expenditure of, on 
 municipal institutions, 5 ; former 
 successful council organization in, 
 16 ; a colonial borough (1686), 50 n. ; 
 history of, as borough or corpora- 
 tion, 52-54, 60, 61 ff. ; receipts 
 from taxes, as colonial borough, 89 ; 
 single-chamber council in, 126 ; 
 number of members of council in, 
 127 ; mode of election to council in, 
 129 ; minority-representation vot- 
 ing schemes in, 131-132; salary of 
 president of council, 134; ordi- 
 nances of, 130 ; statistics of coun- 
 cil, 140; state-appointed police 
 
 2B 
 
 board in (1857-70), 148; extended 
 authority of police commissioner in 
 (1907), 149; tenement house de- 
 partment in, 149-150 ; seaside park 
 for municipal hospitals near, 152; 
 water-supply system for, 153 ; sub- 
 ways in, 154-155; power of grant- 
 ing franchises in, 160; regulation of 
 price of gas in, 161 ; public works 
 officials in, 164-166; tabular state- 
 ment of finances of, 174-180 ; reve- 
 nue system of, 183-189; debt of, 
 188. 
 
 New York State, powers of mayors in, 
 21, 22 ; public works departments 
 in, 24; grouping of related offices 
 in, 25 ; legislative interference in 
 municipal government in, 28; ef- 
 fort to limit special municipal legis- 
 lation in, 30 ; administrative super- 
 vision of schools in, 34. 
 
 Norfolk, Va., a colonial borough, 50 n., 
 61, 62, 65 ff. ; borough charter of, 
 57; council of, 141. 
 
 North Chicago City Railway Com- 
 pany, 232, 237. 
 
 Norwich, Conn., incorporated as a 
 city, 59. 
 
 O 
 
 Oakland, Cal., council of, 141. 
 
 Octrois duties, French, 214. 
 
 Oesterreichisches Stadtebuch, 281-282. 
 
 Officials, municipal, corruption of, 6 ; 
 defects of ignorance and moral 
 deficiency, 7-8 ; appointment of 
 minor municipal, 17-18; chaos in 
 existing arrangements regarding, 
 23-24 ; various provisions as to, 
 24-26; civil service rules applied 
 to, 26, 43-47, 346; in Ohio, 105- 
 106 ; in Italy, 331-333. 
 
 Oglesby, Governor, of Illinois, 234, 
 251. 
 
 Ohio, power of establishing minor 
 offices according to code of, 1718; 
 powers of mayors in, 21 ; depart- 
 ment of public service in, 24-25 ; 
 legislative interference in municipal 
 government in, 28 ; special legisla- 
 tion in, limited, 29 ; new municipal 
 code in (1902), 105-109, 115-118, 
 146 ; members-at-large of councils 
 of cities in, 131 ; municipal plants 
 under new code, 155 ; street railroad 
 franchises in, 158-159; public works 
 boards in, 169, 170, 171 ; Uniform 
 Accounting Law and report on 
 municipal finances in, 285 n.
 
 370 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Oklahoma, municipal ownership au- 
 thorized by constitution of, 158; 
 control of franchises in, 163. 
 
 Omaha, statistics of council, 141. 
 
 Omnibuses, in Chicago, 230-231 ; in 
 London, 296-297; in Berlin, 303, 
 306-307. 
 
 Ontario, report on municipal statistics 
 for, 282. 
 
 Opera houses, municipal, 4. 
 
 Ordinances, power of city councils 
 regarding, and publication of, 139- 
 140. 
 
 Oshkosh, council of, 134 n., 143. 
 
 Ownership. See Municipal ownership. 
 
 Padua, municipal gas-works in, 348- 
 349. 
 
 Paris, tabular statement of finances of, 
 175-179; revenue system of, 209- 
 210, 214, 216 ff. ; municipal owner- 
 ship in, 216. 
 
 Park boards in Cook County, 111., 113. 
 
 Park departments, 4, 150 ; in Indiana, 
 122; notable legislation concerning, 
 152; in New York City, 165, 166; 
 of Chicago, 166; of Philadelphia, 
 167 ; in Boston, 168 ; paid or unpaid 
 boards, 172. 
 
 Parks, in Naples, 335; in Rome, 337; 
 in Florence, 339; in Milan, 341. 
 
 Parmalee, Franklin, 231. 
 
 Partisan-voting, defects of, 8-9. 
 
 Passaic, N.J., council of, 143. 
 
 Paterson, N. J., council of, 141. 
 
 Paving, street, 150; in Munich, 311; 
 in Budapest, 314; in Vienna, 328- 
 329 ; in Naples, 334 ; in Rome, 336 ; 
 in Florence, 339; in Milan, 340-341. 
 
 Pawtucket, R.I., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Pay, of members of councils, 13, 133- 
 134, 140-143; of mayors, 21; of 
 municipal officials in Indiana, 122; 
 of public works officials in various 
 American cities, 166, 167, 168, 170, 
 172. 
 
 Penrose, cited, 55, 65, 68, 74, 76, 78, 
 80, 81, 83, 84, 85, 87, 91. 
 
 Pennsylvania, powers of mayors in 
 four cities of, 22; public works de- 
 partments in, 24; legislative inter- 
 ference in municipal government 
 in, 28; colonial boroughs in, 50, 
 5456; bicameral council in cities 
 of, 126; appointing power of city 
 councils in, 138; state police in, 
 148. 
 
 Peoria, HI., council of, 141. 
 
 Perth Amboy, N.J., a colonial bor- 
 ough, 50 n., 65 ff . ; charter of, 57. 
 
 Philadelphia, competitive examina- 
 tions for filling municipal positions 
 in, 26; a colonial borough (1691), 
 50 n., 60, 61, 62, 64, 65 ff. ; charters 
 of, as borough, 54-55 ; present 
 council of, 126, 127, 129, 134, 140; 
 water purification plant in, 152; 
 administration of public works 
 in, 166-167; tabular statement of 
 finances of, 174-180; mercantile 
 license tax in, 190-191 ; revenue 
 system of, 189-195; debt of, 194; 
 failure of municipal gas plant in, 
 271. 
 
 Pingree, Mayor H. S., 220. 
 
 Pisa, municipal gas-works in, 348 
 349. 
 
 Pittsburg, bicameral council in, 126; 
 mode of election to council in, 129; 
 members of council not paid, 134; 
 statistics of council, 140; water 
 purification plant in, 152; director 
 of public works in, 169. 
 
 Police, municipal, 3, 6, 40 ; state control 
 of, 37, 147-149 ; in colonial boroughs, 
 86-88; of Toledo, 99; mounted 
 (rangers) in Texas and in Arizona, 
 148; in Chicago, 182; in Budapest, 
 314-315; in Austrian cities, 317; 
 in Italian cities, 332-333. 
 
 Police boards, state-appointed, 148- 
 149. 
 
 Police commissioners, 149. 
 
 Poll-tax, in Philadelphia, 191 n. 
 
 Population and representation in 
 councils of various cities, 129130. 
 
 Portland, Me., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Portland, Ore., limitation of council 
 to legislative power in, 19 ; home- 
 rule charter of, 31 ; council of, 141. 
 
 Proportional representation plans (for 
 election of councilmen), 131-133. 
 
 Providence, position of mayor in, 21 5 
 appointing power of council in, 138 ; 
 statistics of council, 140; state 
 police board provided for, 149; 
 metropolitan park commission for, 
 152 ; administration of public works 
 in, 170. 
 
 Public Opinion Law, Illinois, 242. 
 
 Public ownership. See Municipal 
 ownership. 
 
 Public safety, boards of, in Ohio cities, 
 106, 109, 116-117, 149; in Indiana, 
 122.
 
 INDEX 
 
 371 
 
 Public service, boards of, in Ohio, 105- 
 106, 107, 116, 117, 126. 
 
 Public-service privileges, returns from, 
 in New York City, 188; Phila- 
 delphia, 193; St. Louis, 199; 
 Boston, 203; Toronto, 205-206. 
 
 Public-service revenues in Paris, 216. 
 
 Public utilities, municipal ownership 
 of, 262-274. 
 
 Public works boards, 24-25, 164-172; 
 single-commissioner vs. bi-partisan 
 board system, 172. 
 
 Pueblo, Colo., statistics of council, 143. 
 
 Pugh-Kibler code in Ohio, 102. 
 
 Q 
 
 Quincy, 111., statistics of council, 142. 
 
 R 
 
 Racine, Wis., mayor of, not paid, 21 n. ; 
 council of, 143. 
 
 Railways, local service of, in Glasgow, 
 288-289; in London, 299-300; in 
 Berlin, 306. See Street railways 
 and Underground railways. 
 
 Railway terminal and surroundings, 
 Rome, 336. 
 
 Rangers (mounted police) in Texas 
 and Arizona, 148. 
 
 Rapid transit board, New York, 166. 
 
 "Rates" in England, 212. 
 
 Reading, Pa., council of, 141 ; ad- 
 ministration of public works in, 171. 
 
 Real estate, municipal, 295; in Milan, 
 344. 
 
 Recorder, office of, in colonial bor- 
 oughs, 69-70, 76. 
 
 Recreation grounds, 4. See Parka. 
 
 Referendum concerning special legis- 
 lation for Chicago, 114; on fran- 
 chises in Wisconsin and Montana, 
 160; on municipal ownership of 
 Chicago street railways, 243. 
 
 Referendum League, Chicago, 242. 
 
 Revenue from street railway franchises 
 in Berlin, 305. 
 
 Revenue systems, 173-217. 
 
 Rhode Island, state police in, 147; 
 legislation concerning parks in, 
 152. 
 
 Richmond, Ind., state-appointed police 
 board in, 149. 
 
 Richmond, Va., a colonial borough 
 (1742), 50 n. ; council of, 141. 
 
 Ridgely, D., cited, 56. 
 
 Riley, E. S., cited, 65. 
 
 Roads in colonial boroughs, 82-84. 
 
 Rochester, N.Y., council of, 140; 
 
 commissioner of public works in, 
 
 169. 
 Rockford, 111., statistics of council, 
 
 143. 
 
 Rogers, H. W., article by, 48 n. 
 Rome, population of ancient, 1 ; 
 
 municipal conditions in modern, 
 
 336-338. 
 
 S 
 
 Sacramento, Cal., council of, 128, 143. 
 
 Saginaw, Mich., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 St. Joseph, Mo., appointing power of 
 council in, 138 ; statistics of coun- 
 cil, 141 ; state-appointed police 
 board in, 148. 
 
 St. Louis, board of public improve- 
 ments in, 24; home-rule charter of, 
 31; council of, 126, 127, 128, 129, 
 140; pay of members of assembly, 
 134; ordinances of, 139; state- 
 appointed police board in, 148; ad- 
 ministration of public works in, 168 ; 
 tabular statement of finances of, 
 174-180; revenue system of, 195 
 199 ; merchants' and manufacturers' 
 special tax and license, 197-198 ; 
 Budapest compared with, 318. 
 
 St. Paul, bicameral council in, 126; 
 statistics of council, 140; admin- 
 istration of public works in, 170. 
 
 Salary. See Pay. 
 
 Salem, Mass., statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Saloon licenses, New York City, 184, 
 187; Philadelphia, 191; St. Louis, 
 198; Boston, 203; Toronto, 205. 
 
 Salt Lake City, statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 San Antonio, Tex., council of, 131, 141. 
 
 San Francisco, municipal corruption 
 in, 6; council of, 126, 127, 133, 140; 
 state-appointed police board in, 
 148 ; administration of public works 
 in, 170. 
 
 Sanitary improvements, 151-152. 
 
 Savannah, Ga., statistics of council, 
 141. 
 
 Savings banks, municipal, in Vienna, 
 323. 
 
 Schenectady, incorporated as a city, 
 59 ; council of, 142. 
 
 Schools, 4 ; administrative supervision 
 of, 34; unprovided for in colonial 
 boroughs, 88 ; in Italian cities, 332 ; 
 teaching of municipal government 
 in, 350-359.
 
 372 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Scotland, municipal ownership in, 287 
 292. 
 
 Scott, A., cited, 57, 64, 68, 70, 72, 73, 
 74, 75, 77. 
 
 Scranton, Pa., council of, 141 ; director 
 of public works in, 169. 
 
 Seattle, statistics of council, 141 ; ad- 
 ministration of public works in, 171. 
 
 Sewer systems, 150; in New Orleans, 
 151 ; figures in regard to, 151 ; 
 canals used as, in Venice, 346, 347. 
 
 Shauck, Judge, opinion of, quoted, 
 100-101. 
 
 Sheriffs in colonial boroughs, 73. 
 
 Sikes, George C., 241 ; article by, 
 cited, 261. 
 
 Sikes Report, the, 241. 
 
 Sioux City, la., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Sites, C. M. L., cited, 147. 
 
 Slaughter-houses, municipal, in Scot- 
 land, 287; in Leipzig, 309; in 
 Munich, 311 ; in Vienna, 323. 
 
 Smith, E. B., cited, 261. 
 
 Socialists, in Vienna, 321-323; in 
 Florence, 340; in Milan, 344-346; 
 in Venice, 348. 
 
 Somerville, Mass., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 141. 
 
 South Bend, Ind., 119; statistics of 
 council, 142 ; state-appointed police 
 board in, 149. 
 
 South Carolina, state police in, 147 ; 
 franchise statute in (1902), 158. 
 
 South Omaha, Neb., statistics of coun- 
 cil, 143. 
 
 Special legislation for cities, 28-29, 
 110-111, 114-115. 
 
 Speirs, F. W., cited, 191, 193. 
 
 Spezzia, municipal gas-works in, 348. 
 
 Spoils system in cities, 39 ff . ; under 
 public ownership, 267. 
 
 Spokane, council of, 142. 
 
 Springfield, 111., council of, 142. 
 
 Springfield, Mass., council of, 141. 
 
 Springfield, O., council of, 142. 
 
 State police, 147-149. 
 
 Statistics, comparative municipal, 173- 
 218, 275-285; International Con- 
 gress of, 278. 
 
 Statistisches Jahrbuch Deutscher Stadte, 
 279-282. 
 
 Steamers, municipal operation of, in 
 Venice, 347. 
 
 Stewart, Graeme, 243. 
 
 Stith, cited, 50 n. 
 
 Stock transfers, tax on, New York 
 City, 189. 
 
 Street-car tax, St. Louis, 199. 
 
 Street cleaning, 150; statistics as to, 
 151 ; in Chicago, 182. 
 
 Street-lighting, 88 ; question of mu- 
 nicipal administration of, 265-266, 
 271, 273; in Florence, 339. See 
 Electric lighting and Lighting plants. 
 
 Street paving. See Paving. 
 
 Street railways, bearing of new mu- 
 nicipal code in Ohio on, 108 ; no 
 municipal, in United States, 1 54 ; 
 under Illinois act of 1903, 156-157 ; 
 franchises for, 158-163 ; in Chicago, 
 162, 230-259; pros and cons of 
 municipal ownership, 266; munici- 
 pal, in Scotland, 287 ; municipal, 
 in Glasgow, 288-290; municipal, in 
 Birmingham, Eng., 292, 294; in 
 London, 296, 297-299; in Berlin, 
 303-306; in Leipzig, 309; in Mu- 
 nich, 311 ; in Vienna, 323, 326-328 ; 
 in Milan, 332, 341-343; in Naples, 
 334-335 ; in Rome, 337 ; in Florence, 
 339-340. 
 
 Street-sprinkling tax, St. Louis, 199 n. 
 
 Streets, construction and care of, 4 ; 
 in colonial boroughs, 82-84; in 
 Naples, 334; in Rome, 336; in 
 Florence, 339. See Paving. 
 
 Stubbs, quoted, 49. 
 
 Subways, municipal, 154-155 ; in 
 New York City, 165; in London, 
 299; in Budapest, 314. 
 
 Suffrage in colonial boroughs, 62-67. 
 
 Superior, Wis., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Syndic, office of, in Italian cities, 331. 
 
 Syracuse, N.Y., council of, 140 ; com- 
 missioner of public works in, 169. 
 
 Tacoma, council of, 142. 
 
 Taney, Chief Justice, quoted, 251. 
 
 Taunton, Mass., council of, 143. 
 
 Taxation, limitation on municipal, 
 under Illinois law, 113-114. 
 
 Tax commissioners, state, 35; board 
 of, under Ohio code, 117. 
 
 Taxes, in colonial boroughs, 88-94; 
 assessment and collection of, in New 
 York City, 184; in Philadelphia, 
 190; in St. Louis, 196-199; in 
 Boston, 202-203; in Toronto, 203- 
 206; in European cities, 211-218. 
 
 Tax rates, in five American cities, 180 ; 
 in New York City, 186-187; in 
 Boston, 202. 
 
 Telegraph and telephone companies, 
 taxation of, Toronto, 204.
 
 INDEX 
 
 373 
 
 Telephones, regulation of rates by 
 cities, 162; question of municipal 
 ownership of, 266. 
 
 Telephone systems, franchises for, 
 159-163; municipal, in Glasgow, 
 287, 290-292. 
 
 Tenement house department, New 
 York City, 149-150. See Dwell- 
 ings. 
 
 Terre Haute, 119; council of, 142; 
 state-appointed police board in, 
 149. 
 
 Texas, "commission plan" in, 117 n. ; 
 rangers in, 148 ; regulation of rates 
 charged by public utility corpora- 
 tions in, 162. 
 
 Theatres, municipal, 4. 
 
 Thurston, Harry W., 352. 
 
 Toledo, O., legislative acts of 1902 
 affecting, 99-101; council of, 140. 
 
 Topeka, Kan., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Toronto, revenue system of, compared 
 with American cities, 203-206. 
 
 Town clerk, Italian secretary-general 
 corresponds to, 331. 
 
 Town criers in colonial boroughs, 87, 
 88. 
 
 Town-meeting system, 58-59 ; in 
 colonial boroughs, 7475. 
 
 Towns, Massachusetts, 59 n. ; under 
 Indiana municipal law, 119. 
 
 Tramways, municipal, in Glasgow, 
 288-290; in London, 296, 297- 
 299. 
 
 Transportation systems, local, 4 ; in 
 Glasgow, 288-289 ; in London, 296- 
 300 ; in Berlin, 303-308. See Street 
 railways. 
 
 Treasurer, office of, in colonial bor- 
 oughs, 72-73; municipal, in Ohio 
 cities, 105. 
 
 Trenton, N.J., a colonial borough, 
 50 n. ; charter of, 57 ; statistics of 
 council, 141. 
 
 Troy, N.Y., statistics of council, 14] ; 
 commissioner of public works in, 
 169. 
 
 Tuley, Judge M. F., 111. 
 
 Tunnel, East Boston, 154 ; New York- 
 Brooklyn, 155. 
 
 Tweed Ring, 6. 
 
 II 
 
 Ulm, municipal real estate in, 295. 
 
 Underground railways, municipal, 154 
 155; in Glasgow, 288-289; in Lon- 
 don, 296, 299 ; in Berlin, 305. See 
 also Subways. 
 
 Universities, municipal, 4; in Ohio, 
 
 107. 
 Utica, N.Y., statistics of council, 141. 
 
 Valuation of real estate, New York 
 City, 186. 
 
 Venice, municipal conditions in, 346 
 348. 
 
 Vienna, tabular statement of finances 
 of, 175-179; revenue system of, 
 210, 215, 216 ff . ; municipal owner- 
 ship in, 216 ; municipal government 
 in, 316-329. 
 
 Virginia, colonial boroughs in, 50, 56 
 57 ; bicameral council in cities of, 
 126; law affecting cities and towns 
 in, 146 ; municipal ownership in, 
 156 ; franchise question in new 
 constitution of, 159. 
 
 W 
 
 Ward election of councilmen, 13, 14 
 15; in Illinois, 112; in Ohio, 115; 
 in Indiana, 120. 
 
 Wards in colonial boroughs, 74. 
 
 Wash-houses, public, in Scotland, 288. 
 
 Washington, D.C., government of, 
 13 ; no city council in, 140 ; com- 
 parison between Munich and, 309. 
 
 Washington (state), home-rule charters 
 in, 31. 
 
 Waste in municipal work, 6 ; causes 
 of, 7. 
 
 Watchmen in colonial boroughs, 86- 
 88. 
 
 Waterbury, Conn., statistics of council, 
 142. 
 
 Water-gas, in Vienna, 324-325. 
 
 Water purification plants, 152. 
 
 Water supply, 4, 6; of colonial 
 boroughs, 8485 ; question of mu- 
 nicipal ownership of, 265, 271, 273; 
 municipal, in Birmingham, Eng., 
 292, 293-294 ; of Naples, 335. 
 
 Waterworks, municipal, 152-153 ; 
 municipal, under Ohio code, 155 ; 
 franchises for, 158-163; revenue 
 from, in New York City, 187 ; mu- 
 nicipal, in Scotland, 287 ; in Leipzig, 
 309; in Vienna, 323. 
 
 Werno, Charles, 249. 
 
 Westchester, N.Y., a colonial borough, 
 56. 
 
 Wharves in colonial boroughs, 82. 
 
 Wheeling, W. Va., council of, 126, 142. 
 
 Whitehead, W. A., cited, 72, 76.
 
 374 
 
 INDEX 
 
 Whitten, R. H., cited, 147. 
 
 Wilcox, D. F., cited, 20, 97; quoted, 
 47. 
 
 Wilkesbarre, Pa., council of, 141. 
 
 Williamsburg, Va., a colonial borough, 
 50 n., 57, 65 ff. 
 
 Williamson, W. D., cited, 51, 52. 
 
 Williamsport, Pa;, council of, 143. 
 
 Wilmington, Del., council of, 141. 
 
 Winthrop, John, quoted, 51. 
 
 Wisconsin, referendum on franchises 
 in, 160 ; railroad commission super- 
 vises public utilities in, 161. 
 
 Woonsocket, R.I., statistics of council, 
 143. 
 
 Worcester, Mass., council of, 140; 
 administration of public works in 
 171. 
 
 Wyoming, state examiner of public 
 accounts in, 36-37. 
 
 Yates, Governor, 243. 
 
 Yerkes, Charles T., advent of, in 
 Chicago, 237 ; secret activity of, in 
 political affairs, 237-238 ; opposition 
 to measures of, and retirement, 238 
 239. 
 
 Yonkers, N.Y., council of, 141. 
 
 York, Me., 50 n., 52. 
 
 York, Pa., statistics of council, 142. 
 
 Youngstown, O., council of, 142. 
 
 Zone system of street railway fares, 
 270; in Munich, 311-312; in Naples, 
 335; in Rome, 337; in Florence, 
 340 ; does not prevail in Milan, 342.
 
 University of California 
 
 SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 
 
 405 Hilgard Avenue, Los Angeles, CA 90024-1388 
 
 Return this material to the library 
 
 from which it was borrowed.
 
 UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 
 
 A 001 039 566 3