'*>*&? 
 
 Division of Agricultural Sciences 
 
 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 %gm 
 
 m?- 
 
 fyfrAcd ^cti ^AciM^Cncm Mctd 
 
 A. D. REED 
 
 J. H. SNYDER 
 
 CALIFORNIA AGRICULTURAL 
 Experiment Station 
 Extension Service 
 
 CIRCULAR 491 
 
 Revised 
 
 CAECAG491 1-8 (1973) 
 
This circular aims at helping tenants and landlords in drawing 
 up mutually satisfactory leases. The farm lease worksheet sample 
 (see center insert) may he torn out and used to help you deter- 
 mine an equitable rent for your individual lease situation. 
 
 MARCH, 1973 
 
 THE AUTHORS: 
 
 A. D. Reed is Extension Economist, Agricultural Extension, and Associate on the 
 Giannini Foundation, Davis. 
 
 J. H. Snyder is Professor of Agricultural Economics, and Agricultural Economist in 
 the Experiment Station, and on the Giannini Foundation, Davis. 
 
WHAT YOU SHOULD KNOW 
 ABOUT FARM LEASES 
 
 Tenants operate approximately 13 per 
 cent of California farms, but 63 per cent 
 of the land is leased. Included are all 
 types of agricultural enterprises. Rental 
 rates and leasing arrangements vary 
 widely, depending on type of enterprise, 
 productivity, size, location, and the like. 
 Leasing arrangements must be tailored 
 to each individual case but should be 
 based on a mutual feeling of trust, a sat- 
 isfactory potential income for tenant and 
 landlord, a rental rate equitable to both 
 parties, and a written lease using clear, 
 
 understandable words, 
 farm leases 
 
 In short, good 
 
 are periodically reviewed to deter- 
 mine if they are equitable, 
 
 are based, if necessary, on some 
 form of sliding-scale rent (described 
 herein) to reduce undue risk to ei- 
 ther tenant or landlord, 
 
 provide for an automatic renewal 
 unless terminated by either party, 
 
 are in writing — to protect you, your 
 heirs, and your tenant. 
 
 WHAT TO INCLUDE 
 
 Legal advice will help prevent subsequent 
 difficulties. In general, every lease should 
 contain at least the following: 
 Date of lease. 
 
 Names and addresses of all parties con- 
 cerned. 
 
 Description of the property — 
 Location as to county and state, 
 Legal description, 
 Acreage, 
 
 Specification of parcels of land or 
 buildings being retained by the land- 
 lord. 
 Terms of lease — 
 
 Dates of start and termination of the 
 lease, 
 
 Provision for automatic continuation 
 on a year-to-year basis unless termi- 
 nation notice is given by either party 
 before a specified date, 
 
 Rental rates for each enterprise, 
 
 Expenses to be borne by each party 
 
 concerned, 
 
 How, when, and where rent is to be 
 
 paid, 
 
 Management practices to be followed 
 
 for: 
 
 Acreages of crops 
 
 Rotations 
 
 Numbers of livestock 
 
 Improvements, 
 Provision to reimburse tenant at ter- 
 mination of lease for improvements 
 made at his expense and not fully used 
 up, 
 
 Provision for settlement in case of 
 death, 
 
 Provision for arbitration in case of 
 disagreement. 
 Signatures of all parties. 
 
LEGAL REQUIREMENTS 
 
 A lease is a contract, a promise enforce- 
 able by law. 
 
 A valid contract must meet certain 
 legal requirements. Among them are: 
 
 Consent of the parties. All parties to 
 be bound by the contract must consent 
 positively. Lack of a negative answer 
 cannot bind a person to a contract. 
 
 Parties competent to enter into con- 
 tract. Persons under 18 generally do not 
 have full legal capacity to make con- 
 tracts; neither do insane persons, intoxi- 
 cated persons, and convicts. Corporations, 
 by their charter, may have limited con- 
 tracting power. 
 
 Consideration is the price which one 
 party pays for another's promise. The 
 price need not be in terms of money but 
 is essentially the conduct, or the promise 
 of conduct, of one party given in ex- 
 change for the conduct, or promise of 
 conduct, of the other party to the trans- 
 action. 
 
 Purpose of the contract must be legal. 
 
 Contracts which cannot be performed 
 within one year must be in writing to be 
 enforceable. 
 
 L nder California law, leases of land for 
 agricultural purposes for a period longer 
 than 51 years are not valid. 
 
 DETERMINING THE RENT 
 
 Rent, being the price for the use of land 
 or other productive factors, is determined 
 by demand and supply. There are, how- 
 ever, many reasons why it is difficult for 
 tenant and landlord to arrive at and to 
 maintain a rental arrangement fair to 
 both. 
 
 Rents often become established at a 
 "customary" rate. But there are situa- 
 tions where no customary rate has been 
 established, such as for enterprises which 
 have not normally been rented, or for 
 new enterprises developed in an area. 
 
 But also in situations where customary 
 rates have been established, tenants and 
 landlords will do well to constantlv reap- 
 praise the existing rates, or they nun find 
 
 themselves at a disadvantage. Rental rates 
 should respond to changes in cost-price 
 relationships, introduction of new ma- 
 chinery, development of higher-yielding 
 varieties, production shifts from one area 
 to another, increasing farm size, need for 
 greater managerial ability, and others. 
 
 This circular cannot, of course, de- 
 termine the rent for you. This is your 
 job to be done by individual bargaining. 
 This circular, however, presents to you 
 a method that will assist you in arriving 
 at equitable rental rates. 
 
 An equitable rent, as usually defined, 
 is one where landlord and tenant share 
 the gross income in the same proportion 
 as they contribute to the costs of pro- 
 duction. To establish a fair rent: 
 

 
 FARM LEASE WORKSHEET 
 
 Owner Tenant Date 
 
 
 Farm 
 
 INVESTMENT EXPENSE 
 
 
 Total 
 Investment 
 
 Landlord 
 
 Tenant 
 
 Investment 
 
 Interest 
 
 Depreciation 
 
 Investment 
 
 Interest 
 
 Depreciation 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Buildings 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Irrigation system 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fences 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Trees, vines, crops 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Harvest equipment 
 
 Livestock 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Operating capital 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TOTAL 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF EXPENSE 
 
 NONCASH COSTS 
 Interest 
 
 Total 
 value 
 
 Landlord 
 
 Tenant 
 
 Description 
 
 Value 
 
 Description 
 
 Value 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CASH COSTS 
 Hired labor (cultural) 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Hired equipment 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Dust 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Seed 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Fertilizer 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Spray material 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Gas & oil 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Repairs 
 
 Water or power 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Harvest 
 
 Feed 
 
 Veterinary 
 
 Supplies 
 
 Hull & dry 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Dwelling 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Other 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TOTAL COSTS 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Percent 
 
 100 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Digitized by the Internet Archive 
 
 in 2012 with funding from 
 
 University of California, Davis Libraries 
 
 http://archive.org/details/whatyoushould49173reed 
 
Determine the contributions made by 
 each party, 
 
 Assign appropriate values to these con- 
 tributions, 
 
 Establish the share of the total costs 
 
 contributed by landlord and tenant. 
 
 List the following contributions in 
 
 some logical manner. Use of a form like 
 
 the farm lease worksheet (center insert) 
 
 may be helpful. 
 
 Noncash Costs 
 
 Investment. The capital or investment 
 furnished by each party is made a part 
 of annual costs by including interest on 
 such investments. Figure land at a sound 
 agricultural value. Few agricultural ten- 
 ants can pay a rent which reflects sub- 
 division values. Figure buildings, equip- 
 ment, and other depreciable facilities at 
 current depreciated values, or at about 
 half of the replacement cost. Include only 
 necessary items and only at values which 
 would ordinarily provide adequate fa- 
 cilities. Neither party should include in- 
 vestments of unnecessary or overly ex- 
 pensive buildings and equipment. Figure 
 interest on the total investment of each 
 party at an agreed-upon rate, such as 
 6 or 7 per cent. Interest actually paid on 
 debts by either party is ordinarily not 
 considered; such outlays are covered by 
 total interest on the investment. 
 
 Depreciation. The annual decline in 
 value of buildings, irrigation system, 
 equipment, trees, and other capital in- 
 vestments through use or increasing age 
 is a proper part of annual costs. Esti- 
 mate depreciation by dividing cost of 
 each facility by probable useful life. 
 
 Unpaid labor. Make an allowance for 
 the actual operator and family labor fur- 
 nished by each party at going wage rates 
 and include it in the total costs. 
 
 Management allowance. This may also 
 be a proper part of total costs; if so, list 
 it under distributions of expenses divided 
 in the same way as the landlord and 
 tenant share in the managerial duties 
 
 and responsibilities. Management can be 
 valued on the basis of charges made by 
 professional managers — for example, 5 
 per cent of the gross income for actual 
 management, or 10 per cent where the 
 manager also defrays costs of office fa- 
 cilities, accounting, travel, and other ex- 
 penses associated with management. 
 
 Cash Costs 
 
 Credit each party with production, har- 
 vesting, and overhead cash expenses paid 
 by that party. These costs may be esti- 
 mated from previous records, from recent 
 cost studies, or from cost standards, such 
 as enterprise data sheets, available from 
 such sources as the University of Califor- 
 nia Agricultural Extension Service. These 
 expenses are important, so considerable 
 care and local inquiry are justified. 
 
 Dwelling 
 
 A dwelling furnished by the landlord and 
 used by the tenant can be included in the 
 investment of the landlord. In this case, 
 interest and depreciation plus cash costs 
 of taxes, repairs, and insurance would be 
 credited as annual costs contributed by 
 the landlord. 
 
 It is, however, preferable to keep the 
 dwelling completely separate from the 
 contributions of the landlord, and include 
 a provision that the tenant pay a cash 
 rent for its use. This method separates the 
 home from the business, and places a 
 market value rental on its use rather than 
 tying the house rent to the productivity 
 of the farm. 
 
 The Final Computation 
 
 After listing the annual contributions of 
 landlord and tenant, add each list and 
 determine the proportion which each 
 party contributes to the total production 
 cost. 
 
 The percentage contributed by the 
 landlord can be used as the share rent, or 
 it can be multiplied by the probable price 
 to arrive at a cash rent. If the percentage 
 
Owner J«^ J/oe 
 
 
 FARM LEASE WORKSHEET 
 
 Tenant A Aof Date 
 
 Farm f~7i(>c4>sst«.f 
 
 J^iu^/aes at a« acre /6ss/<> - Uh>d(*~*£ are*^ 
 
 
 
 INVESTMENT EXPENSE 
 
 
 
 Total 
 
 Investment 
 
 Landlord J 
 
 Tenant 
 
 
 Investment 
 
 Interest |^ depreciation 
 
 Investment 
 
 Interest £*quipreciation 
 
 Land 
 
 Buildings 
 
 Irrigation system 
 
 Fences 
 
 Trees, vines, crops 
 
 Tractors & trucks 
 
 Machinery 
 
 Harvest equipment 
 
 Livestock 
 
 Operating capital 
 
 ) 
 
 f <?co 
 
 #<?oo 
 
 tf*£3 
 
 
 
 
 
 /S 
 
 /f 
 
 z. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 £ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 / io 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 V7 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TOTAL 
 
 1 
 
 * rt 
 
 
 
 J77 
 
 
 
 
 DISTRIBUTION OF EXPENSE 
 
 NONCASH COSTS 
 Interest 
 
 Depreciation 
 Unpaid labor 
 Management allowance 
 
 CASH COSTS 
 Hired labor (cultural) 
 
 Hired equipment 
 
 Contract work 
 
 Herbicide 
 
 Dust 
 
 Seed 
 
 Fertilizer 
 
 Spray material 
 
 Gas & oil 
 
 Repairs 
 
 Water or power 
 
 Harvest 
 
 Feed 
 
 Veterinary 
 
 Supplies 
 
 Hull & dry 
 
 Taxes 
 
 Insurance 
 
 Office expense 
 
 Dwelling 
 
 Other 
 
 < 
 J 
 
 Total 
 value 
 
 Landlord 
 
 Tenant 
 
 Description 
 
 Value 
 
 Description 
 
 Value 
 
 ^ A/f 
 
 
 *7/ 
 
 
 * 77 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 %9 
 
 
 
 
 2? 
 
 57 
 
 
 
 
 S7 
 
 3 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 •» 
 
 
 
 
 2. 
 
 £ 
 
 
 
 
 4 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 /s- 
 
 
 
 
 AT 
 
 // 
 
 
 
 
 // 
 
 23 
 
 
 
 
 33 
 
 -xo 
 
 
 
 
 2.0 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 >s- 
 
 
 
 
 /C 
 
 / 7C 
 
 
 
 
 /TO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 /7 
 
 
 '7 
 
 
 
 /9 
 
 
 
 
 /? 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TOTAL COSTS 
 
 / WVsr 
 
 
 * M 
 
 
 * #S7 
 
 Percent 
 
 100 
 
 
 "- 
 
 
 9« 
 
 of the costs furnished by the landlord is 
 loo far from the usual or "customary" 
 share, and it is desired to use the cus- 
 tomary rate, some of the contributions 
 may be shifted from one party to the 
 other to make the percentages fit the local 
 rental rate. Changing the contribution 
 from oik 1 party to the other may also 
 equalize the risks borne by the landlord 
 and tenant or contribute to more efficient 
 use of some resources, e.g., where ferti- 
 lizer cost is divided between the parlies. 
 This method does not determine what 
 the exact rent should be, but provides a 
 
 guide as to what the rent might be. The 
 exact rent must be determined by bar- 
 gaining between the parties, considering 
 prevailing local rates. 
 
 A Sample Worksheet 
 
 The worksheet for a tomato lease shown 
 above illustrates the procedure that can be 
 used to determine an equitable rent of 16 
 per cent. Although this rate is the pre- 
 vailing one, current rents range from 15 
 to 20 per cent, depending primarily on 
 what the landlord furnishes. 
 
Sliding Scale or Flexible Rents 
 
 Many landlords and tenants find a slid- 
 ing scale or flexible rent desirable. Under 
 these arrangements, the amount of cash 
 rent or the percentage of share rent 
 varies with price, yield, or income. In 
 some cases, the rent varies in direct pro- 
 portion to the change in price, yield, or 
 income; other arrangements include some 
 arbitrary deviation from the direct 
 relationship. Usually, rent variations ac- 
 companying changes from a direct rela- 
 tionship between rent and price result in 
 the landlord assuming a larger share of 
 the risk associated with price or yield 
 drop than would otherwise be the case. 
 The landlord is able to stand this risk 
 because a larger proportion of his con- 
 tributions to the business is noncash. 
 
 Sliding- scale cash rent. Under this sys- 
 tem, the cash rent is usually set to vary 
 with the price of the product. A basic 
 rental rate is usually established at some 
 stipulated selling price. Then provisions 
 are made for set increases or decreases 
 in the rent as prices rise or fall. The actual 
 rent is determined only after the com- 
 modities are sold and the actual selling 
 price is known. Where several marketing 
 outlets are available, it may be desirable 
 to base the rent on some established and 
 well recognized market quotation for the 
 product rather than on the actual selling 
 price. This protects the landlord from 
 poor marketing practices by the tenant, 
 and gives the tenant the advantage when 
 he does a particularly good job of mar- 
 keting. 
 
 The amounts of rent actually paid 
 under these systems do not necessarily 
 change in direct proportion to the changes 
 in price. In many cases they are set up so 
 
 that proportionately less rent is paid at 
 low prices and higher rent at high prices. 
 
 Sliding-scale share rent. Since the ac- 
 tual rent collected by the landlord under 
 a share rent agreement varies proportion- 
 ately with the yield and with the price, 
 there is not a great deal of interest in a 
 sliding scale share rent. However, this 
 method is used in some areas of relatively 
 high risk. 
 
 A sliding-scale share rent is based on 
 price or on yield. If based on price, the 
 share rent is established at some given 
 price, and goes up or down with the ac- 
 tual price received. 
 
 For example, the 16 per cent rent in the 
 tomato example given on page 6 might 
 be established at a price of $30 per ton. 
 If the price increased to $32, the rent 
 might be 17 per cent or, if the price 
 dropped to $15, the rent would be 15 per 
 cent. There is periodic interest in this 
 type of rental rate but very few actual 
 leases are drawn up on this basis. 
 
 A sliding-scale share rent based on 
 yield is more common, particularly in 
 areas of rather frequent near failures of 
 the crop. Usually the tenant pays no rent 
 if the yield drops below some predeter- 
 mined level, and the share rent gets pro- 
 gressively higher as the yield increases. 
 
 A variation to the above is where no 
 rent is paid below a certain yield level, 
 but above this point the rent is higher 
 than that indicated by the method of de- 
 termining equitable rents. 
 
 Sliding-scale share rents have to be 
 based on some arbitrary agreement, be- 
 cause these arrangements are a deviation 
 from the equitable rent which would be 
 obtained by using the method described 
 
earlier. These arrangements can be de- 
 fined as equitable only in terms of easing 
 the burden of the tenant under conditions 
 
 of low price or low yield. They represent 
 protection against unusual, but potential- 
 ly disastrous, income hazards. 
 
 DEVELOPMENT LEASES 
 
 The method which we have described for 
 determining annual rent can also be used 
 to determine the rent under a develop- 
 ment lease. The inputs of the landlord and 
 the tenant can be accumulated during the 
 
 development period, after which they be- 
 come a part of the contribution during 
 the rent-paying period with depreciation 
 and interest being charged over the rent- 
 paying period of the lease. 
 
 Co-operative Ex.en.cn work In Agrfc-hur. and Home Econor.es, Kj*n of ^gj-nj *^e^ 
 
 co-operating. Distributed in furtherance of the Acts of Congress of May 8, and June 30, 1914. George B. Aicorn, uirecio , 
 
 LOw 3,'73(Q7993L) PAD