LIBRARY OF THE UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA. "Deceived Jfels^L^ , 189$ Accession No. ^/ [3^0 . Class No. STUDIES IN ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE EDITED BY W. A. S. HEWINS, M.A. THE HISTOEY OF LOCAL BATES IN ENGLAND THE LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE 9 JOHN STREET, ADELPHI, LONDON, W.C. The special aim of THE LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE is the study and investigation of Economic and Political Institutions as they exist, or have existed, in the United Kingdom and in foreign countries. The School provides training in methods of investigation, and affords facilities for original work in Economics and Political Science. Many of the Lectures and Classes are designed to promote a wider knowledge of modern com- mercial conditions, and to meet the needs of those engaged in the Civil Service, municipal employment, journalism, teaching, and public work. PUBLIC LECTURES AND CLASSES are held on Economics, Statistics, Commercial History and Geography, Commercial and Industrial Law, Banking and Currency, Finance and Taxation, and Political Science. SPECIAL CLASSES, arranged as a Three Years' Course of Study, are held twice a week in each subject. Students also carry on their studies under the DIRECT PERSONAL SUPERVISION of the Lecturer. THE LECTURES are usually given between 6 and 9 P.M. THE CLASSES are held both in the evening, between 6 and 9 P.M., and during the daytime. THE ADVANTAGES OF THE SCHOOL ARE OPEN TO MEN AND WOMEN. ' THE SCHOOL YEAR commences in October. There are TJJBEE TERMS, each about ten weeks in duration, viz., (i) October to December ; (2) January to March ; (3) April to July. STUJUCNTS MAY JOIN THE SCHOOL AT ANY TIME. THE FEES FOR FULL STUDENTS ARE 3 A YEAR, OR i A TERM. Students may also be admitted to one or more Courses of Lectures and the classes in connection with them, on the payment of fees varying with the length of the course. SCHOLARSHIPS are awarded to students of ability to enable them to pursue their studies at the School, and a RESEARCH STUDENTSHIP of ^100 a year for two years will be awarded in July 1896. STUDIES IN ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE are in course of publication under the editorship of the Director of the School. All communications should be addressed to the Director, W. A. S. HEWINS, M.A., The London School of Economics and Political Science, 9 John Street, Adelphi, London, W.C. THE HISTORY OF LOCAL BATES IN ENGLAND FIVE LECTUBES BY EDWIN CANNAN LONGMANS, GREEN, AND CO. LONDON, NEW YORK, AND BOMBAY 1896 BF THE S.4ME AUTHOR A HISTORY OF THE THEORIES OF PRODUCTION AND DISTRIBUTION IN ENGLISH POLITICAL ECONOMY FROM 1776 TO 1848. RIVINGTON, PERCIVAL AND CO. 1893. ELEMENTARY POLITICAL ECONOMY. Fourth Thousand. OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS. 1888. Printed by BALLANTYNE, HANSON & Co. At the Ballaniyne Press PREFACE THE lectures which are here published in a some- what amplified form were given for the London School of Economics and Political Science in November and December 1895. The fact that the words " Five Lectures " appear on the title-page will, I hope, protect me from attack on the ground that I have not dealt with the whole subject. To do so in five lectures would be obviously impossible. It was necessary to select a part; and, as is explained in the text, I haye selected the part which interests the urban occupier who thinks his landlord ought to pay the rates, the urban landlord who fails to agree with him, and the rural landlord and farmer who are united in believing it unfair that certain kinds of property not possessed by them should escape being rated. The authorities employed are sufficiently indicated in the text and notes. I have to thank Mr. Hewins and Professor Cunningham for directing my atten- tion to several which have been of much use. OXFORD, January 1896. STUDIES IN ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE EDITED BY W. A. S. HE WINS, M.A. Arrangements have been made for the publication of a series of books containing the results of researches in economic and political subjects conducted by the teachers of the London School of Economics and Political Science, or under their direction. The following volumes are in preparation : 1. THE HISTORY OF LOCAL RATES IN ENG- LAND. By EDWIN CANNAN, M.A., Balliol College, Oxford. 2. THE REFERENDUM IN SWITZERLAND. By SIMON DEPLOIGE, University of Louvain. Translated, with Introduction and Notes', by C. P. TREVELYAN, M.A., Trinity College, Cambridge. 3. SELECT DOCUMENTS ILLUSTRATING THE HISTORY OF TRADE UNIONISM, i. THE TAILOR- ING TRADE. Edited by F. W. GALTON. With a Preface by SIDNEY WEBB, LL.B. 4. SELECT DOCUMENTS ILLUSTRATING THE STATE REGULATION OF WAGES. Edited, with Introduction and Notes, by W. A. S. HEWINS, M.A. , Pembroke College, Oxford ; Director of the London School of Economics and Political Science. 5. HUNGARIAN GILD RECORDS. Edited by Dr. JULIUS MANDELLO, of Budapest. 6. THE RELATIONS BETWEEN ENGLAND AND THE HANSEATIC LEAGUE. By Miss E. A. MAC- ARTHUR, Vice-Mistress of Girton College, Cambridge. CONTENTS i PAGE ANCIENT NON-STATUTORY RATES TO 1601 i II MISCELLANEOUS STATUTORY RATES TO 1640 . . 27 POOR-LAW RATES TO 1601 54 IV THE POOR-RATE SINCE 1601 . . . . 78 V ASSIMILATION OF OTHER RATES TO THE POOR- RATE ........ 102 INDEX . ...... 137 HISTORY OF LOCAL RATES IN ENGLAND i ANCIENT NON-STATUTORY RATES TO l6oi LABORIOUS students whoso investigations have in- terested scarcely any one but themselves have been known to seek comfort in the assertion that truth is valuable for its own sake. I do not believe that this is the case. A great deal that is true is not worth knowing. The most inveterate bore is often the most truthful of men. All history should, I think, have some practical aim. Some moral, some lesson or guidance, should be afforded by it. Even if this is not true of all history, it is surely true with regard to economic history. It would be absurd to study a subject so dry, not to say so odious, as local rates except with a view to practical aims. We do not study such subjects from a love of truth in the abstract or to while away a wet Sunday afternoon, but because there are practical controversies about them, and we hope that we may learn something which may be of assistance in these controversies. Recognising this frankly, I intend to try to collect together those facts only which explain the origin and progress of the two great characteristics of our 2 History of Local Rates rating system which give rise to most complaint. I mean, of course, the characteristic facts that rates are paid only in respect of certain kinds of property, and are levied from the occupiers and not the owners of that property. With the practical inferences to be drawn from the information I hope to furnish, I shall not meddle here. To do so would be to abandon the attitude of impartiality appropriate to the occasion ; and besides, I think the practical inferences to be drawn are so clear that they scarcely need to be expressed. Almost all the money raised by English local taxa- tion at present is raised either by means of the poor- rate or by means of other rates which, though they have names of their own, are in reality nothing but additions to the poor-rate. It is consequently natural for the legal mind, which never goes behind a statute, to explain the fact that occupiers are rated in respect of certain property by a simple reference to the act of 1601, on which the poor-rate is based to this day. In June 1894 the deputy-chairman of the London County Council, in examination before the House of Lords Committee on Betterment, ventured to suggest that the reason people are rated on property is "because it is the best criterion of the measure of the ease with which a person can bear rating." Lord Salisbury remarked that this was " rather a formidable doctrine to lay down," Avhereupon the present Lord Chancellor said, " The reason you are rated is because the act of Elizabeth says you shall be." * But, first, 1 Report from the Select Committee of the House of Lords on Town Improvements (Betterment], No. 292 of 1894, Minutes of Evidence, Questions 2011-14. Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 3 as the witness did not fail to point out, there must have been reasons for the act of Elizabeth ; and, secondly, the act does not, as a matter of fact, say you shall be rated in the way you are rated. It says that the money required for poor relief in each parish shall be raised "by taxation of every inhabitant, parson, vicar, or other, and of every occupier of lands, houses, tithes impropriate, propriations of tithes, coal- mines, or saleable underwoods." 1 This surely is far from being a correct and adequate description of our present poor-rate. It is incorrect, because by no means every inhabitant, whether parson, vicar, or other, is taxed. It is inadequate, because occupiers of lands, houses, tithes, coal-mines, and saleable under- woods, are taxed on a peculiar and minutely regulated basis the annual value of the thing occupied whereas the words of the act say nothing about the basis of the taxation, and would by themselves cover an income-tax, a poll-tax, and many other taxes. The reference to the act of 1601 thus takes us a very little way. We want to know how and why that act came to say what it does say, how and why its words have come to bo interpreted in the way they are interpreted, and how and why all other rates have been swallowed up by the particular rate established under it. A preliminary question has to be answered. What is a rate ? A kind of tax, no doubt ; but what kind ? From the phrase " rates and taxes," and the common grumble, " It isn't the taxes, it's the rates that I 1 The words have been misquoted in Bott, Poor- Laws, ist edition, and perhaps elsewhere (see Cowper, Reports, p. 559), "other" being inserted before "occupier," and the sense thus greatly altered. 4 Plistory of Local Rates complain of," it would be tempting to conclude that " rates " is merely another name for local taxes. Doubtless, " rates " are now practically synonymous with local taxes in England. But this is a mere accident. If a man has nothing but ducks, his poultry and his ducks are the same thing, but it does not follow that poultry is merely another name for ducks. It is only a few years since the London coal- duty was abolished, and that was certainly a local tax which no one would call a rate. In other countries local taxes not of the nature of rates flourish exten- sively. The real difficulty is not to find a local tax which is not a rate, but to find any tax which is not local. A New York State tax is local in relation to the United States, and so is a Prussian national tax in relation to the German Empire. A true imperialist would regard the insular imposts which we call " im- perial taxes" as local ; and if British and New Zealand taxes are local, there seems no reason why German and Austrian imperial taxes should not be looked upon as local. Moreover, while it is easy for a tax to be local without being a rate, it is at least logically conceivable for a rate to be world-wide. The real difference between a rate and a tax which is not a rate appears to lie entirely in the manner in which the financial problem of raising money is approached. In the case of a tax, the taxing authority decides that individuals shall make particular pay- ments on particular occasions, and the aggregate sum it receives depends on how much these payments add up to. In the case of a rate, the taxing authority decides how much money it wants in the aggregate, and this amount is raised by apportioning the pay- Non-Statutory Rates to 1 60 1 5 inent of it between the various ratepayers in ac- cordance with some definite standard made for the occasion or already in existence. Thus, in the case of a tax the procedure is by way of addition, and in the case of a rate by way of division ; in the case of a tax the taxing authority hopes it will get a certain sum, in the case of a rate it knows that it will get it. All our national taxes would be turned into rates if Parliament merely decided that so many millions were to be raised from beer, so many from death- duties, so many from income-tax, and so on, and left it to the Treasury to impose the rates necessary in order to raise the sums prescribed. In these days the yield of a tax can generally be estimated with such accuracy that the distinction is not of practical importance. It can make no differ- ence whether the Chancellor of the Exchequer says, " An income-tax of 8d. will produce so many millions, which is what we require," or "We want so many millions, and that will necessitate an income-tax of 8d." But when all estimates of the yield of taxation were wild guesswork, and taxes had an extraordinary capacity for falling far below the estimates, the differ- ence between the two methods was of the greatest moment. In the case of a large area like that of the whole country, it would evidently be impracticable to adopt the rate method by apportioning the payment of a lump sum among all the taxpayers. But in the case of an area small enough for the taxpayers to be known to the taxing authority and each other, and to feel a common interest in raising the sum required, the rate is the simplest and most obvious method of meeting common expenses that can possibly be 6 History of Local Rates conceived. If, then, we were to argue on eighteenth- century principles, from an " original state of things " in which independent men began to combine in society, we should probably be inclined to place the origin of local rates, either in money or services, almost as early as the institution of civil government. To do this, however, would be a mistake. Many of the most expensive institutions now maintained by local rates had no existence in the Middle Ages. Even the fifteenth-century citizen had not to provide for compulsory education, purification of sewage, street lamps, or police in the sense in which we now use the word. There were always roads, of course, but what were those roads like ? Those who have con- tended that English roads were good in the Middle Ages must, I think, have done so without much per- sonal acquaintance with the roads of to-day. You may travel many thousand miles and not find the smallest thing to suggest that the road was what we should consider tolerable centuries ago, and yet you will see vast quantities of evidence to show that it was thoroughly bad in fact, not what a townsman would now call a road at all. For ninety-nine miles out of a hundred it must have been what rustics now call a " soft " or " green " road, in contradistinction to the " hard " or metalled road of the modern highway authority. 1 It keeps along the hillside regardless of gradient, because some embanking and draining would have been necessary on the flat land. It is sinuous 1 Ploughing up the highway was an offence known to the law. In 1286 the commonalty of Cambridge were charged with ploughing up the highway to Hinton marsh. C. H. Cooper, Annals of Cam- bridge, 1842, vol. i. p. 61. Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 7 owing to the effort to avoid every soft place ; and where the adjacent landowners have observed the eighth commandment, it is excessively wide between the hedges, because on a " green " road the traffic is constantly endeavouring to find a place where previous passengers have not destroyed the surface. Every improvement obviously dates from the turnpike days. If we wish to picture an English road in the Middle Ages, we should think of what we now call a mere "track" across an open heath, or imagine a wide, little-used country road, with the narrow metalled strip in the middle entirely removed. The cost of public works was to some extent defrayed by the benevolence of private individuals and religious houses. Testators bequeathed property for building or maintaining bridges, as in the case of the Bridge House estates of the city of London. Monks improved the roads in the neighbourhood of their convent; an excellent half-mile of road across the flood-lands of the Thames still testifies to the energy of the monks of Abingdon. The preamble of an act of 1554 (i Mar., st. 3, c. 6) tells us not only that the road between Gloucester and Bristol, one of the most important cross-roads in the king- dom, had so fallen into decay that many passengers had lost their lives on it, but also that it had been formerly "well repaired by the devotion of divers good people." The remainder of what we regard as the expenses of local government, so far as they existed, were borne on the broad back of the " feudal system." Consider the first general highway act, which was passed as late as 1555 (2 & 3 P. & M., c. 8), remember- 8 History of Local Rates ing that it is to bo looked on as an attempt to secure and extend what was regarded as the best custom, rather than as an extravagant innovation. It orders the constables and churchwardens to call together the parishioners once a year, and elect two honest persons to be surveyors or orderers of the works for amend- ment of the highways in their parish leading to any market town. The constables and churchwardens are to appoint four days for the amending of the high- ways, and " shall openly, in the church the next Sun- day after Easter, give knowledge of the same four days, and upon the said days the parochians shall endea- vour themselves to the amending of the said ways, and shall be chargeable thereunto as followeth : that is to say, every person for every plough land in tillage or pasture that he or she shall occupy in the same parish, and every other person keeping there a draught or plough, shall find and send, at every day and place to be appointed for the amending of the ways in that parish as is aforesaid, one wain or cart, furnished after the custom of the country with oxen, horses, or other cattle, and all other necessaries meet to carry things convenient for that purpose, and also two able men with the same, upon pain of every draught making default I os. ; and every other householder, and also every cottager and labourer of that parish able to labour and being no hired servant by the year, shall, by themselves or one sufficient labourer for every of them, upon every of the said four days, work and travail in the amendment of the said highways, upon pain of every person making default to lose for every day 1 2d. ; and if the carriages of the parish or any of them shall not be thought needful by the Non-Statutory Rates to 1 60 1 9 supervisors to be occupied on any of the said days, that then every person that should have sent any such carriage shall send to the said work for every carriage so spared two able men, there to labour for that day, upon pain to lose for every man not so sent to the said work I2d. And every person and car- riage aforesaid shall have and bring with them such shovels, spades, picks, mattocks, and other tools and instruments as they do make their own ditches and fences withal, and such as be necessary for their said work : and all the persons and carriages shall do and keep their work as they shall be appointed by the said supervisors or one of them, eight hours of every the said days, unless they shall be otherwise licensed by the said supervisors or one of them." I think every one will agree that all this reads a great deal more like an account of the feudal services of tenants on a manor than a description of a highway rate. There is no attempt to make the amount of service rendered vary with the varying requirements of different seasons and different districts. It is true that the lawyers held that, if the labour prescribed by the act was not sufficient to keep the roads in repair, the parishioners ought to give more labour ; l but this was a legal counsel of perfection of no practical im- portance. The whole system was so alien to the system of rating that the " statute labour," as it was called, never developed into a rate. It lingered on to the present century, 2 alongside of turnpikes and rates. Bridges too, which were much more expensive works in comparison with roads than they are now, 1 See Dalton, Country Justice, erl. of 1742, p. 115. 2 Till the passing of the act 5 & 6 W. IV., c. 50. io History of Local Rates were generally maintained by obligations of a feudal character, particular bridges being burdens on par- ticular lands. 1 Thus it comes about that the importance of local rates is not so ancient a matter as we might be tempted to expect on general considerations. I doubt if any very clear and important cases of local rates are likely to be found earlier than the thirteenth century. Plenty of such cases, however, existed in the middle of that century. The customs of Romney Marsh, which then were at any rate old enough to be described as " ancient and approved," required certain services from the men of the marsh which are marked by the distinguishing characteristics of a local rate. In 1250, we read, some dispute occurred between the twenty- four jurats of Romney Marsh and certain men of the marsh, who were bound to repair the sea-walls and watercourses according to the quantity of their lands and tenements. Sir Henry de Bathe, the justiciar, was appointed to hear and determine the contentions which had arisen, and issued an ordinance from which, as Coke says, not only other parts in Kent but all England received light and direction. 2 According to this ordinance, " By the whole com- monalty of the same marsh twelve lawful men may be chosen, to wit, six of the fee of the Archbishop of Canterbury, and six of the barony, which, being sworn, 1 Lands so liable sometimes formed the basis of a kind of corpo- ration. The " lands contributory to Rochester Bridge," for example, had two wardens, twelve assistants, and a commonalty. See 18 Eliz., c. 17, and 27 Eliz., c. 25. 2 Sir William Dugdale, History of Embanking and Draining of Divers Fens and Marshes, 1662, pp. 17-19 : Coke, Inst. iv. c. 62, p. 276. Non-Statutory Rates to 1 60 1 1 1 shall measure the walls new and old, and those which ought to be new erected. And the same measuring should be done by one and the same perch, to wit, of twenty foots. And afterwards the same jurors upon their oaths also by the same perch shall measure by acres all the lands and tenements which are subject to danger within the same marsh : which measurings being done, the twenty-four by the commonalty first elected and sworn, having respect to the quantity of the walls, lands, and tenements which are subject to peril, by their oath shall ordain how much appertaineth to every one to uphold and repair the same walls. So that for the portion of acres of lands lying subject to danger there be assigned to every one his portion of perches by certain bounds." l If any man neglected to repair the portion assigned to him, the common bailiff might do the work, and charge him with double the cost. Where land was held in common by partners, a portion of sea-wall was to be assigned to these partners in common. No suggestion is made that the quality or value of the acres as well as their number ought to be taken into account, but an ordi- nance issued by Lovetot and Apulderfield in 1287, extending the laws of Romney Marsh westwards into Sussex, speaks of the walls being apportioned among individuals according to the extent and value of their acres (juxta portionem acrarum suarum et valorem earundem). 21 I do not think that the mere fact that the sea-walls themselves, instead of the money cost of maintaining them, were apportioned among the men of the marsh ought to prevent us from regarding this as 1 The Charter of Romney Marsh, Latin and English, 1686, p. 12. 2 Ibid., pp. 49, 50. 12 History of Local Rates an early sewers rate; and in any case before 1359 the practice of each man maintaining a particular portion of the defences seems to have been superseded by a system of money rates. A commission was issued in that year to the king's well-beloved and trusty Thomas Ludlow, Robert Belknap, and Thomas Culpeper, in consequence of complaints made by the Archbishop of Canterbury, who was lord of a portion of the marsh. This alleges, without any apparent jus till cation, that the ordinance of Henry de Bathe provided for the election of a bailiff " to levy the assessments " (ad scotta assessa levandum) for the repair of the defences. 1 In 1256, 20 193. 2d. was levied from the county of Chester for the repair of Chester Bridge, " because the King had ascertained from the book of the Ex- chequer called Domesday that the men of the county were bound to repair the bridge." 2 According to the passage in Domesday referred to, but not quoted, a man was to be sent from every hide to repair the city wall and bridge, 3 so that we see here an old feudal obligation transformed into a county rate. There is nothing to show whether the 20 193. 2d. was appor- tioned according to hides or in some other way. 4 1 The Charter of Romney Marsh, pp. 55-57. 2 Madox, Firma Buryi, 1726, p. 89. a "Ad murum civitatis et ponteiu reaedificandos de unaquaque hida comitatus unum hominem venire prsepositus edicebat. Cujus homo non veniebat dominus ejus XL solidos eraendabat regi et comiti. Ha3C forisfactura extra firmam erat." 4 In 1287-8 an agreement was made between the barons, knights, and free tenants of the county and the mayor and city of Chester, by which the latter grant that they will repair a part of the bridge. "The expense thereof is also to be shared by all the town and foreinsec lands which, being comprehended in the book called Domesday in the Treasury of London, within the 52 hides reckoned Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 13 From 1334 onwards the fifteenths and tenths were levied as local rates. They were originally, of course, a national tax on movables, at the rate of one-tenth of the capital value in the cities and boroughs and lands belonging to ancient demesne, and one-fifteenth from the rest of the country. But after 1334 it became a settled principle that each Parliamentary grant of a fifteenth and tenth should be subject to the condition that the tax should be levied like the last, and not otherwise. 1 This was intended, or at any rate understood, to mean that the total sum collected should remain exactly the same, and be apportioned in exactly the same way between county and county, town and town, and even parish and parish. As the relative wealth of the different dis- tricts changed, the tax of course ceased to be collected at a uniform rate over the kingdom, and consequently within the city of Chester, shall be found liable to pay tax. The county is burdened with the rest of the bridge." Ormerod and Helsby, History of Cheshire, 2nd edit., 1882, vol. iii. p. 891. 1 See Stubbs, Constitutional History, vol. ii., 282, p. 599, lib. edit., and of the authorities there quoted, especially Brady, Treatise of Cities and Boroughs, 1690, p. 39. The grant of 1344 was in these terms : "And the said commons do grant to him for the same cause upon a certain form, ii Quinzimes of the Commonalty and ii Dismes of the Cities and Boroughs, to be levied in manner as the last Quinzime granted to him was levied, and not in other manner " (Statutes of the Realm, 18 Edw. III., stat. 2, c. l). Similarly, in 1357 : "The said commons have granted to our sovereign lord the King a quinzime yearly to be levied and gathered in the manner as the last quinzime granted to the King was levied" (ib., 31 Edw. III., st. i, c. 13) ; and two centuries and a half later, in 1623-4 : " Three whole fifteens and tenths shall be paid, taken, and levied of the movable goods, chattels, and other things usual to such fifteens and tenths to be contributory and chargeable within the shires, cities, boroughs, towns, and other places of this your Majesty's realm, in manner and form aforetime used" (ib., 21 Jac. I., c. 33). 14 History of Local Rates came to possess the one essential characteristic of local taxation, diversity of rate as between place and place. The duty of the collectors in each parish was simply to apportion a fixed sum among the inhabi- tants, which is precisely the function of those who assess local rates. An inhabitant disproportionately assessed could go to the courts and demand redress on exactly the same grounds as those on which a modern ratepayer relies when he appeals against his assessment to the poor-rate. Madox quotes the case of one Johanna, widow of John Nicole, of Guildford, against the sub-collectors of that town. She appeared before the Barons of the Exchequer, by John of Holt, her attorney, and said for the King and herself, that, whereas the town of Guildford was assessed to the tenth at ^15 2s. iod., and that sum ought to be pro- portionately assessed among the men of the town according to the quantity of their goods, without favouring any one, and although the aforesaid Johanna paid the proportion rightly due from her, which amounted to 2os. if she was assessed like the other men of the town, to the aforesaid sub-collectors on the 3oth of April, the aforesaid sub-collectors assessed the said Johanna to 408. beyond the aforesaid 2os., in order to favour the other men of the town. The sub- collectors answered that the said Johanna was assessed just as the other men of the town were assessed, and the case went to a jury to decide the facts. 1 This happened in i 354. ; Church rates were well established by the beginning of the fourteenth century. John of Athon, a canonist who wrote about the year 1 340, sa} r s in his notes to ,, x Madox, Firma Buryi, pp. 281, 282. Non-Statutory Rates to 1 60 1 15 the Constitutions of Otho and Ottobuoni : " Every parishioner is bound to repair the church according to the portion of land which he possesses in the parish, and in proportion to the number of animals he keeps and feeds there." 1 A constitution issued by John Stratford, Archbishop of Canterbury, in 1342, ordains that "as well the religious as all others that now have, or shall hereafter have, possessions, lands, or revenues which are not of the glebe of the churches to be repaired, or of the endowments that belong to them, in any parishes whatsoever of our province, whether they dwell in the said parishes or elsewhere, shall be obliged to pay with the other parishioners toward all the charges which are either of common right or by custom incumbent on the parishioners for the repair of the church and the orna- ments belonging thereto, according to the quantity of the possessions and revenues which they have in the said parishes, as often as there shall be need for the same." 2 Enforcement of church rates belonged to the ecclesiastical authorities and courts, but they were none the less compulsory for that, and on one ground or another they occasionally came under the cognis- ance of the secular courts. An important case of this kind is recorded in 1370. A parish meeting had decided to raise 10 to repair the roof of a certain parish church. One of the parishioners objected to a distraint for 98. which had been levied on him, upon 1 " Credo tamen contra sc. quod unusquisque parochianus teneatnr ad hoc juxta portionem glebse seu terrae quam possidet intra ipsam parochiam et juxta numerum animalium qua) nutrit ibidem." Lyndwood, Constitutioncs Legatincc D. Othonis et D. Othoboni, cardina- liurn cum profundis annotationibus Johannis de Athona, 1679, p. 113. 2 Lyndwood, Provincial e seu Constitutioncs Anylia*, 1679, p. 255. 1 6 History of Local Rates the grounds that the collection should only be en- forced by the ordinary, and that he had not assented to the rate. The collectors of the rate pleaded custom which had always existed time out of mind. Kirton, one of the judges, remarked, "There is a custom through the whole country which the laws call by- law, that is, by assent of neighbours to levy a sum to make a bridge, a causeway, or a sea-wall, and by their assent to assess each neighbour at a sum certain, for which they may distrain. And also if commoners have common rights in a place, they can by assent ordain that they shall not exercise the right in a certain parcel of land before a certain time, and if they do that they shall be distrained." In both cases, he thought, the assent of those who were present at a properly summoned meeting bound those who were absent. His colleague, Finchden, said, " If this ordi- nance concern a thing which would be to the common hurt, that is, for a bridge, to make a causeway or sea- wall, you are right ; but if it be for their particular profit, as in your case of the common, no man will be bound but those who assent." In this case the 10 was raised by an assessment of 6d. in respect of each carucate of land, id. in respect of each head of cattle, and the same in respect of every ten sheep. 1 The canonist Lyndwood, writing about 1430, says that the quantity of a man's possessions and revenues should be estimated for rating purposes by their value. 2 With our modern notions of the separate province 1 Year Book. (ed. 1679), Edward III., anno xliv., p. 19. Part of the translation of Kirton's opinion is from Chief Justice Tindal in Phillimore, Buries Ecclesiastical Law, 1842, vol. ii. p. 388/1. 2 "Qure considerari debent secundum valorem reditus." Prorin- ciale, p. 255, Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 17 of imperial and local government, we find it strange to read of town fortifications paid for out of local funds, but this was the regular rule, and when other sources of income did not suffice, a rate could be raised for this purpose. There exists a royal letter of 1378 ordering that the walls of Chichester shall be repaired, and that " all persons whatsoever, religious or secular, who now have, or in future shall have, lands, tenements, and revenues or merchandise within the city or its liberty," shall contribute to the cost " according to their ability and possessions, privileged persons, the sick, and mendicant poor excepted." Similar letters were sent to other towns. 1 The purposes for which a corporate town in the four- teenth or fifteenth century required money were indeed almost as multifarious as they are to-day, for though we have multiplied our wants, we have also relegated some expenses to the state, and others to private enterprise or benevolence. In many cases, no doubt, the corporate revenues and profits sufficed to defray all expenses. Even at the present day they are often sufficient to make it unnecessary to levy a borough rate, though no borough is rich enough to do without a rate for the expenses of its Council acting as urban sanitary authority. But at any rate in the poorer boroughs resort to local taxation was often necessary. In early times equal poll-taxes seem to have been levied. The London riot in 1 196, of which William FitzOsbert was regarded as the instigator, is said to have been a revolt 1 Kymer, Fcedcra, R. iv. 52, and 49, 59 : 0. vii. 185. As late as 1607 the inhabitants of Southampton had "a long time at their own cof't and charge upheld and maintained the walls thereof, with many towers, turrets, bulwarks, great ordinances, powder, and other offensive artillery" (Statutes of the If calm, 4 Jac. I., c. 10). B 1 8 History of Local Rates of the poorer citizens against such a tax. 1 Poll-taxes in which persons were taxed according to their rank are found at a very much later period. At Ipswich in 1451 every portman was to pay 38. 40!., every burgess i s. 8d., and every foreigner i s. ; and in the next year every portman was taxed is. 8d., and every burgess is. 2 But by the fifteenth century, at any rate, the money for defraying the common burdens was, as Madox says, usually raised by an apportionment made amongst the townsmen according to each man's ability and sub- stance. 3 There is no town, so far as I know, of which we have better records during this period than Ips- wich. Here are some entries in Bacon's Annals relat- ing to the proceedings of the governing body of the town with regard to rates from 1452 to 1488 : Oct. 13, 1452. Every burgess of this town shall pay J of a 1 5th for certain affairs of this town, and collec- tors specially named. Jan. 21, 1454. Accompt shall be made before auditors assigned of the money received for the suits between this town and that of Bury St. Edmunds and the prior of Ely. May 17. Six collectors named to assess all the inhabitants of this town at J quinzieme for the suit aforesaid. Jan. 7, 1455. Every burgess of this town shall pay J of a quinzieme towards the suits between this town 1 Stubbs, Constitutional History, vol. i. 161, p. 657, lib. ed. 2 The Annals of Ipswich : the Laws, Customs, and Government of the same, collected out of the Records, Books, and Writings of that Town, by Nathaniel Bacon, serving as Recorder and Town Cleric in that Town, anno dom. 1654. Edited by W. H. Richardson, 1884. 3 Firma Burgi, p. 280. Non- Statutory Rates to 1601 19 and the town of Bury, and every foreign burgess shall also pay thereto. April 1 1. The collectors of money of certain parti- cular parishes in Ipswich for the suit with Bury have a day set to bring in their accounts. March 10, 1458. The burgesses of this town shall pay J of a I5th for the suit with the prior of Ely, and collectors are appointed. May 5. All burgesses refusing to pay their part of the said assessment shall be disfranchised. Oct. 2. Collectors for J of a i5th granted for tJffe suit with the prior of Ely. Dec. 14. Collectors made for J of a i5th for charges of a suit wherein John Geete was condemned against Gregory Lanham, and for other urgencies of the town. Oct. 4, 1459. A sum of money assessed upon parti- cular persons named for the maintaining of the suit [with the king]. Dec. 30, 1472. Auditors appointed and collectors of the contributions of the several parishes for the repair of the common quay. March 7, 1485. Assessors named for the charges for renewing the town charter, and the Serjeants are ordered to levy the same. June 26, 1486. Assessors named for a sum of money for the king's entertainment at his next coming. March 13, 1487. Ten assessors named for 50 marks pro regardo Domini Regis when it shall be demanded. Jan. 8, 1488. An assessment shall be made for the town charter renewing, and assessors and collectors mentioned and named in every parish. May 30. An assessment shall be made for a loth 2o History of Local Rates and 1 5th for the king, and assessors and collectors nominated in each parish. We need scarcely go further to convince ourselves of the frequency of rates in Ipswich before the era of the poor-rate. Several of the later entries, however, are worth quoting for various reasons. In 1495 occurs an excellent example of the use of the fifteenth and tenth for purely local purposes. " Assessors and col- lectors in each parish for a moiety of a tenth and a fifteenth for the repair of the new mill, the whole sum being 18 48. 6d." The practice, which reminds us of the modern French centimes additionels, was not confined to Ipswich. It prevailed in London at least as late as 1587.* In 1538 Ipswich levied a distinctly sanitary rate. Bacon's entry is : " Constables assigned to several wards to remove nuisances, and to levy money to pay carts for their carriage of the filth away." In 1545 we get a little more light as to the principle followed in assessing the rates. Every port- man was to pay ios., and every one of the four-and- twenty, 53. ; " and every of the commons shall be rated according to their substance by two honest persons within their parish." No doubts as to the 1 See Orders appointed to be executed in the City of London for setting Rogues and Idle Persons to Work, and for Relief of the Poor, 1587, re- printed 1793 : " 57. For the provision of the said stock to the accomplishment of the said good works, there may be granted by the body of this city two fifteens, to be assessed and levied in usual manner, whereof the one to be paid as speedily as may be, the other one at the end of six months." In 1614 Ipswich used the subsidy in the same way as the fifteenths. A benevolence of ^200 was to be rated by the subsidy, "and if the same fall short," says Bacon's entry, " it shall be rated upon the better sort of the inhabitants to make up the sum." Non- Statutory Rates to 1601 21 legal powers of the governing body to impose rates seem to have been felt till 1549. In that year assessors were appointed " to assess the burgesses and inhabitants " to pay " scott and lott for the town debts. And the bailiffs shall assess the assessors. Provided if the order be found contrary to the king's laws, the same shall be void." The doubts must have been set at rest, as the order was confirmed in the next year, and the precedent was followed in 1558. In 1592 there was rating for a preacher's wages, and in 1 597 the burgesses' salary was rated on the inhabitants. In those days ratepayers appear to have been expected not only to pay, but to refrain from grumbling, for we find that, on 4th December 1573, " Richard Golty, one of the burgesses of this town, being allotted to the sum of 408., did upon the 10 of October, in the presence of two persons of credit, say that the scott and lott rated, on him was done against reason, con- science, charity, and honesty; and being convicted thereof, he was fined 5, and ordered to pay the said 408." It would have been a miracle if Tudor legislation had succeeded in creating a rate altogether unaffected by the uninterrupted rating practice of three centuries. To understand our present system, based upon the act of 1 60 1, it is therefore necessary to know something about the principles on which these early non-statutory rates were apportioned. The sewers-rate of Romney Marsh presents no diffi- culty. It was clearly governed by the principle that each person whose property was benefited should pay a proportion governed by the acreage, and afterwards the value, of that property, in comparison with the 22 History of Local Rates whole of the property benefited. But if we look at the other rates through modern spectacles, the prin- ciple on which they are based is not very evident. The cloud which obstructs our vision will disappear, however, if we once abandon the pernicious modern habit of asking what was ratable. It is never things, but always persons, that pay rates and taxes, and in the fourteenth or even the sixteenth century the metaphor which attributes payment to the thing in respect of which the person is taxed had not taken possession of the ordinary mind as it has now. In the simplest form of rating there is nothing in the nature of an assessment or valuation list made up by a modern assessment committee. The total sum to be raised is apportioned directly upon the contributors as the assessors think fit or the common agreement decides. It seems quite clear that in the fourteenth and fifteenth century the accepted view was that each inhabitant should pay according to his ability or substance, 1 for in those days ability and substance meant much the same thing: the man who has a large income without having a large capital is a pro- duct of modern civilisation. Something in the nature of a valuation list soon sprang up, not because there was as yet any idea that the things of which a man's substance consists ought to be rated, but because the assessors wanted some kind of guide as to the relative ability or substance of the ratepayers. In a purely 1 In Latin, "juxta facilitates." See the letter to Chichester, quoted above, p. 1 7, and another in Ryraer, Fcedera, R. vol. iii. Part i. p. 57, A.D. 1345, giving directions for the reassessment of Tarn worth to the fifteenth after a fire: "Vobis mandamus quod omnes et singulos homines dictse villse juxta facultates suas quas modo habent de novo taxari." Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 23 agricultural community, where every person of ability to pay is a farmer, nothing can be more natural than that the assessors, in forming their estimate of relative ability, should consider the number and quality of the acres cultivated by each, and perhaps also the number of sheep and cattle pastured. In a town, an equally obvious guide as to the substance of the inhabitants is afforded by the size or value of the houses occupied. 1 When this has once become the settled custom, it is supposed by a natural confusion of mind that the acres and the houses are taxed, and any attempts to carry out the original principle of rating according to ability derived from every source are strenuously re- sisted by the parties interested. The owner of lands or houses which he has let for a rent objects to being rated in accordance with his whole substance, on the ground that the rates on his lands and houses have 1 Even the fifteenths and tenths, which were in their origin fractions of movable property only, seem to have been assessed in accordance with the annual value of tenements occupied before they ceased to be granted. The language of Parliament is vague. In 1562-3 (by 5 Eliz., c. 31), for example, it grants "two whole XV nos and X th8 to be payd, taken, and levied of the movable goods, catalles, and other things usual to such XV noa and X th8 to be contributory and chargeable." Scattered allusions show that the " other things " had long included property occupied. We find, for example, in 1377-8, the revocation of a writ which exonerated the chancellor and scholars of Cambridge University from tenths and fifteenths in respect of their tenements, possessions, and books (Cooper, Annals of Cambridge, 1842, vol. i. p. 116). In 1385 the ex- emption was re-established, tenements, schools, and books being mentioned (ibid., p. 129, cf. 'p. 197). Orders of the city of London issued in 1587 ( 58 ; see above, p. 20 n.) speak of foreigners being contributory to the fifteenths "by the rate of their houses." In a church-rate case heard in 161 1, the court talked of " a rate imposed according to the value of the land, and that in the nature of a fifteen " (Bulstrode, Reports, i. 20). 24 History of Local Rates already been paid by his tenants. 1 The tradesman, the money-lender, and the salaried servant or official decline to pay their full proportion, on the ground, as they say, that it has never been the custom to rate stock-in-trade, money, or salaries. On the other hand, by way of compensation, whether it acquiesces will- ingly in these contentions or not, the taxing authority insists on having rates in respect of all the lands and houses within its jurisdiction from the occupiers, whether the ability or substance of those occupiers is indicated by the value of their occupations or not, and whether they are resident inhabitants or not. The whole process may be seen going on in Coke's report of the famous case of Jeffrey, which came before the King's Bench in 1 5 89. The church of Hailsham was out of repair, and it was estimated that the cost of repairing it would be not less than jo. The churchwardens " for the time being, anno domini 1589 and two years before, with the assent of the greater part of the parishioners of the said parish, juxta quantitatem et qualitatem possessionum et reddituum infra dictam parochiam existentium according to the quantity and quality of the possessions and revenues within the said parish determined and agreed to make a taxation for the repair of the said church." Notice of the parish meeting was given in the church and proclaimed in the market, and on the appointed day " the church- wardens and the greater part of the parishioners of Hailsham who were there met together, made a tax, 1 Lord Mansfield said in 1776, "The landlord is never assessed for his rent, because that would be a double assessment, as his lessee has paid before " (Cowper, Reports, p. 453). N on- Statutory Rates to 1601 25 scil, of every acre of marsh land 4d, and of every acre of arable land 2d., to be paid by the occupiers of them in Hailsham ; " and " all the said tax of the said town did not exceed the sum of ,50." Now one William Jeffrey, gentleman, who resided, not in Hailsham, but in Chiddingley, some miles away, both owned and occupied 30 acres of the marsh land and 100 acres of the arable land so rated. He objected to pay his 26s. 8d., on the ground that he was not a parishioner of Hailsham. Suffering defeat on this point before the spiritual court, he invoked the civil, but met with no better success. After taking the opinion of the ecclesiastical lawyers, the court decided that he was a parishioner and liable to be rated. " It was answered and resolved, first, that although the house wherein Jeffrey dwelt be in another parish, yet forasmuch as he had lands in the parish of Hailsham in his proper possession and manurance, he is in law parochianus de Haylesham. For the place where he lies, sleeps, or eats, doth not make him a parishioner only; but also, forasmuch as he manures lands in Hailsham, and by that is resident upon it, that makes him a parishioner of Hailsham also as to this purpose. If," continued the court and here no doubt is the crucial point " in this case Jeffrey should not be charged to the reparation of the church of Hailsham for those lands which he himself occupies there, no person would be charged for them, upon which great incon- venience would ensue; for one who inhabits in the next town may occupy the greatest part of the lands in another town, and so churches in these days will come to ruin." One of Jeffrey's complaints was that the churchwardens had said that he "occupied or 26 History of Local Rates received rent " for the 1 30 acres, whereas it would, he alleged, " be against law and reason, and against the common experience of all England," that he should be rated if he had let the land. In response to this complaint, the court, which had not then the horror of giving unnecessary decisions it now feels, resolved that " when there is a farmer of the same lands, the lessor who receives rent for them shall not be charged for them in respect of his rent, because there is an inhabitant and parishioner who may be charged, and the receipt of the rent doth not make the lessor a parishioner." While thus throwing over the old principle in favour of the new and more convenient practice, the court was still willing to do lip-service to the old principle, for it observed, " In this case the charge is on the person, and not on the land, but is on the person in respect of the land, for the more equality and indifferency." Coke was counsel in this case himself, and he says at the end of his report, " Note, reader, this is a good case to many purposes, and therefore well observe the consequences of it." l 1 Reports, Pt. v. pp. 67, 68. II MISCELLANEOUS STATUTORY RATES TO 1640 THE unsophisticated mind, which cherishes the delu- sion that our financial institutions have been created by politicians instead of by the force of circumstances, would naturally suppose that as soon as we come to rates imposed or regulated by statute, we should find no difficulty in discovering how rates were assessed and upon whom they were laid. This expectation would be disappointed. The early statutes take a great deal for granted, and are often least explicit just at the point where we most desire information. The first of them is the sewers act of 1427 (6 Hen. VI., c. 5), which authorised the king to appoint commissions to supervise works for sea defence wherever they might be required. Within their several jurisdictions the commissioners were to be empowered to inquire by whose default damages had arisen, and " who doth hold lands and tenements, or hath any common of pasture or fishing in those parts, or else in any wise have or may have the defence, profit, and safeguard as well in peril nigh as from the same far off, by the said walls, ditches, gutters, sewers, bridges, causeys, and weirs, and also hurt or commodity by the same trenches, and there to dis- train all them for the quantity of their lands and tenements, either by the number of acres or by their ploughlands, for the rate of the portion of their 28 History of Local Rates tenure, or for the quantity of their common of pasture or fishing, together with the bailiffs of liberties and other places ... to repair the said walls, ditches," and so on, " so that no tenants of lands or tenements, nor any having common of pasture or fishing, rich or poor, nor other of what condition, station, or dignity which have or may have defence, commodity, and safeguard by the said walls," and all the other things, " or else any hurt by the said trenches, whether they be within liberties or without, shall in any wise be spared in this." Necessary and convenient statutes and ordinances might be made by the commissioners according to the laws and customs of Romney Marsh, and they were to hear and determine all complaints according to the law and custom of England and the custom of Romney Marsh. After being renewed several times, this act was superseded by the 23rd of Henry VIIL, c. 5 (1531-2), which authorises the commissioners to inquire " who hath or holdeth any lands or tenements or com- mon of pasture or profit of fishing, or hath or may have any hurt, loss, or disadvantage, as well near to the said dangers, lets, and impediments, as in- habiting or dwelling thereabouts by the said walls . . . and all those persons and every of them to assess, charge, distrain, and punish as well within the metes and bounds of old time accustomed as else- where within our realm of England after the quantity of their lands, tenements, and rents by the number of acres and perches after the rate of every person's portion, tenure, or profit, or after the quantity of their common of pasture or profit of fishing or other commodities there." If the tax on any lands, tene- Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 29 ments, or hereditaments was not forthcoming, the commissioners might " decree and ordain " them from their owners. Crown land was to be subject to the same laws as all other land. 1 It is evident that the general principle of the early sewers rates or taxes for sea defence was that they should be levied in respect of all kinds of property liable to danger, in proportions determined by the extent or value of that property. But the ordinances and statutes certainly do not make it very clear to the modern mind from whom the taxes were to be levied when the owner and the occupier or tenant were dif- ferent persons. On this point we may take the opinion of Mr. Serjeant Callis, who delivered lectures on the Statute of Sewers (23 Hen. VIII., c. 5), at Gray's Inn, in August 1622. As he was for many years a commissioner of sewers in his native county of Lin- colnshire, he must have been acquainted with the practice as well as the strict law of the matter. He says that we must " distinguish and make a difference between annual repairs in ordinary things and extra- ordinary repairs. For to furnish the defence with petty reparations, they shall be laid only upon the lessee for years or for life ; but if a new wall, bank, or goat or sewer, be to be built new and erected, or if the ancient defences be decayed in the main timber, or in the principal parts thereof, here as well the lessor as the lessee shall be put to the charge, for these things be not ordinary and annual charges, but do reach from the beginning of the lease to the top of the inheritance. 1 Before this time the king had often voluntarily contributed his share, recognising that the sea would not respect his lands any more than that of his subjects. See Dugdale, Embanking, pp. 88-90. 30 History of Local Rates As for petty reparations, they are by intendment to continue but for a short tune, which are likely to be spent during the term and lease; but these new defences are apparently done to save the inheritance." He quotes as analogous the case of landlord's and tenant's repairs to a house, and concludes that "in petty annual and ordinary repairs the lessee alone shall do the same ; but where the same wants in great timber or when a new defence is to be built, they shall both be at the charge." The fact is that the commis- sioners had a very wide discretion, and could, in Callis's words, apportion the tax " as in justice, dis- cretion, and true judgment is requisite." x Just before the Statute of Sewers conies the Statute of Bridges (22 Hen. VIII., c. 5), passed in 1530-1, because, as the preamble says, " in many parts of this realm it cannot be known and proved what hundred, riding, wapentake, city, borough, town, or parish, nor what person certain or body politic, ought of right " to repair bridges which had fallen into decay. It is easy to believe that a good stone bridge would often outlast the memory of the oldest inhabitant, especially when he had an interest in forgetting. For a remedy the act provides that in all cases where it is doubtful on whom the obligation to repair a bridge lies, " the said bridges, if they be without -city or town corporate, shall- be made by the inhabitants of the shire or riding in which the said bridge decayed shall happen to be ; and if it be within any city or town corporate, then by the inhabitants of every such city or town corpo- rate." It then gives the justices of the counties and !. Reading on the Statute of Servers, 1647, pp. no, in ; 2nd edit., pp. 141-143- Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1 640 3 1 towns power and authority to call before them the constables, or else "two of the most honest inhabi- tants," of every town or parish within the area charge- able, and with their assent "to tax and set every inhabitant in any such city, town, or parish within the limits of their commissions and authorities to such reasonable aid and sum of money as they shall think by their discretions convenient and sufficient for the repairing, rectifying, and amendment of such bridges." After this taxation has been settled, the justices are to " cause the names and sums of every particular person so by them taxed to be written in a roll indented." The act is extremely minute on many points of detail which seem unimportant to us, but it does not tell us who the " inhabitants " were, nor on what principle the justices were to proceed in appor- tioning the tax among them. Coke, in his Institutes, says that the word "inhabitant" does not include servants and such-like persons who have nothing upon which distraint could be levied, and that it does in- clude a non-resident who has lands or tenements in his own possession and manurance within the area of liability. Such a non-resident, he adds, "is an in- habitant both where his person dwelleth and where he hath lands or tenements in his own possession within the statute." l His opinion as to the ratability of non-resident occupiers is founded on Jeffrey's case, not on anything in the act itself, nor on any legal decision under it. He also remarks that the taxation cannot be set on the hundreds, parishes, and towns in lump sums, but must be assessed on individual in- habitants. This is doubtless the true meaning of the 1 Institutes, ii. p. 702. 32 History of Local Rates act, but all the same the practice was to rate the areas in lump sums, and leave them to apportion these sums among the inhabitants as they thought fit. 1 An act of a local character (23 Eliz., c. n), passed just fifty years later, shows that in taxing and setting each inhabitant to a reasonable aid the justices were expected to follow well-known precedents. A dispute had broken out between Cardiff and Glamorgan about the duty of repairing the bridge at Cardiff. " Such doubts and ambiguities," the preamble of the act says, were discovered "touching certain words and sen- tences " in the Statute of Bridges, " that more money was like to be spent in the determining and explain- ing of the same than haply might have sufficed to have re-edified the said bridge." To put an end to this unhappy state of affairs, Parliament declared that of right the building of the bridge belonged to the town without all doubt or controversy, but at the same time it ordered the county to bear five-sixths and the town only one-sixth of the cost, in considera- tion of " the poor estate of the said town of Cardiff, and the inability thereof to perform so great a charge." To avoid any "doubts and ambiguities" as to the method of raising the contributions of the town and the county, it went on to enact that the justices hi the county and the mayor and bailiffs in the town were " to rate and assess the county aforesaid, with the several hundreds, and every town corporate, parish, village, and hamlet within the same, and every inhabitant and dweller within every and any of them, 1 See, for a Norfolk example in the first half of the seventeenth century, Bodleian MS., Tanner, 311, f. 257. The practice seems to have been first legalised in 1702 by i Ann., c. 12. Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 33 to such reasonable sum and sums of money as to them shall be thought meet and convenient, in due and proportionable manner, according as rates, tasks, and tallages have been before this time used to be there rated and levied, or as near thereunto as they can." If we suppose, as we reasonably may, that this provision was intended to declare the meaning of the Statute of Bridges rather than to alter or add to it, we may infer that in 1580 good authorities were of opinion that the taxation under that statute should be apportioned as rates, tasks, and tallages had usually been apportioned. Thus the statute, instead of clearing anything up, merely throws us back on pre-existing custom. Close upon the Statute of Bridges follows an act for building county jails (23 Hen. VIII., c. 2), passed in 1531-2. This authorised the justices of twenty- five of the counties to call together the high con- stables, tithing-men, or borough-holders, of every hundred, lathe, or wapentake of the shire, and by their assents, agreements, and discretion, tax and set every resident in the shire having land, tenements, rents, or annuities of estate of inheritance or for time of life to the clear yearly value of 408. or above, or being worth in movable substance the clear value of 20 or above. Here is one bright spot in the midst of obscurity. The persons to be taxed owners of pro- perty real and personal, " resident," not " inhabiting," in the shire are plainly specified, and it is clearly implied that they are to be taxed in proportion to the value of the income derived from their property, movables being assumed to produce an income of 10 per cent, on their capital value. c 34 History of Local Rates The statute next in order, passed in the follow- ing year (24 Hen. VIII., c. 10), leaves everything undetermined. It enacts that the tenants and in- habitants of every parish, township, hamlet, borough, or village with more than nine inhabited houses, shall, "at their own proper costs, charges, and expenses, provide, make, or cause to be made one net " for the destruction of choughs,' crows, and rooks, which " do daily breed and increase " throughout the realm, and " do yearly destroy, devour, and consume a wonderful and marvellous great quantity of corn and grain of all kinds," besides causing a " marvellous destruction and decay of the covertures of thatched houses, barns, ricks, stacks, and other such-like." Three years later we find an act (27 Hen. VIII., c - 63, 1535-6) regulating the government of Calais, and providing for its representation in Parliament. This prescribes that the necessary 2s. a day for the wages of the burgesses in Parliament shall be " levied in such manner of form as within other cities and boroughs within this realm is used and accustomed." The same reference to well-established custom is found in the act of 1543-4 (35 Hen. VIII., c. 11), making provision for the payment of the represen- tatives of Wales. The sheriffs of the twelve Welsh counties and Monmouthshire are to gather and levy the fees of the knights of the shire from "the in- habitants of the said twelve shires, and of the said county of Monmouth, which ought to pay the same." The boroughs which did not send burgesses of their own to Parliament were grouped for electoral purposes with the county town, and so, in order to provide for the wages of the burgesses in Parliament, the justices . Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 35 were to " lot and tax every city, borough, and town," and the "rates so rated and taxed in gross" were to be "again rated and taxed on the inhabitants of every of the said cities and boroughs by four or six discreet and substantial burgesses of every the said cities and boroughs in Wales thereunto named and assigned by the mayor, bailiffs, or other head officers of the said cities, towns, and boroughs for the time being." An act of 1 545 " for the marshes besides Greenwich " (37 Hen. VIII., c. 11) says that most of the owners of the said marshes pay " a rate for an acre " towards the repairing of the banks which protect the land from the tide, "yet some owners thereof be which have not nor will not pay anything." These re- fractory individuals are therefore made liable to distraint. More interest attaches to an act of 1545-6 (37 Hen. VIII., c. 14) "for Scarborough Pier." This recites that formerly when the harbour was in good con- dition the inhabitants and dwellers were prosperous, " and also all the owners of all the messuages, lands, and tenements within the precinct of the said town did set and let their said messuages, lands, and tene- ments at great rents or farms, to their great advan- tages and profits," but now that the quay or pier had been partially destroyed and the safety of the har- bour impaired, the inhabitants and dwellers were im- poverished, and the rents and farms were hindered and diminished. Parliament thereupon considered that if the pier were repaired, the lands and houses "might be set or letten for much greater rents or farms," and also that the tenants and farmers were 36 History of Local Rates not able to repair the quay unless the owners were "compelled to be yearly contributors and helpers." It therefore authorised the bailiffs, coroners, and searchers of occupations in Scarborough to appoint two masters or keepers of the pier, and enacted that these masters or keepers and their successors, should yearly levy, towards the repair and subsequent main- tenance of the pier, one-fifth of the rents receivable by "all and every person and persons being owner or owners, and having estate of inheritance, or being tenant by the courtesy or tenant in dower of any messuage or messuages, tenement or tenements, or any kind of rents, garthings, orchards, or other lands, grounds, or hereditaments set, situate, or lying within the precincts, limits, or bounds of the said town of Scarborough, or the liberties and jurisdiction of the same, or of any kind of rent or rents being due to be paid forth, or for any of the same." The fifth was to be collected from the farmers or occupiers, but it is provided that every occupier holding under a landlord, upon paying the fifth part of his rent to the masters of the pier, " shall be thereof and for so much clearly acquitted and discharged against the owner" from whom he holds, "any usage, custom, law, covenant, indenture, obligations, or bonds to the contrary made or hereafter to be made in any wise notwithstand- ing." To make a long story short, tenants were allowed to deduct the fifth from their rents, and all contracts to the contrary, past, present, and to come, were rendered void. If any owner occupied or held his property in his own hands, he was to pay the fifth part of so much rent as it " may be reasonably let to farm for, as by the valuation of ten discreet persons Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 37 of the same town shall be adjudged without fraud or coven. In setting aside past and future contracts on the part of tenants to pay rates, this act is unique, but the paving acts of the period afford examples of the practice of authorising deductions from rent where no such contracts existed. It is not very easy to see how a road through a town came to be distinguished from a highway in the country, but it seems to be the case that the duty of repairing the streets in a town lay upon the owners (not on the occupiers) of the property abutting upon them. The liability of the corporation was often admitted in the case of large public places, like market squares, but not in that of ordinary streets. The owners on each side were ex- pected to pave the way as far as the channel, which in those days, of course, was in the middle of the road, not on each side between the carriage-way and the footpaths. The enforcement of this obligation, if it is not exactly the same thing as the imposition of a rate apportioned according to frontage and width of street, is very closely analogous, and in later times it cer- tainly developed into a rate. The first paving act in the Statutes of the Realm was passed in the year 1532-3 (24 Hen. VIII., c. n). It recites that the common highway between Charing Cross and the Strand Cross is " very noyous and foul, and in many places very jeopardous " to passengers on foot or 1 The 45. in the pound being fixed, whatever the requirements of the pier might be, was, strictly speaking, a tax rather than a rate. It was, however, a tax in respect of things usually ratable ; and from the fact that the owners were to be " contributors and helpers " with the tenants, we may gather that the proceeds went in aid of an ordinary rate. 3 8 History of Local Rates horseback, because " the landlords and owners of all the lands and tenements next adjoining" it have been "remiss and negligent, and also refuse and will not make and support the said highway with paving, every of them after the portion of his ground adjoin- ing." It is therefore enacted that " all and every person and persons, their heirs and successors, the which now, or at any time from henceforth, shall be seized in possession or in use of any manor, lands, or tenements in any wise adjoining to the said highAvays ... of any estate of fee-simple, fee-tail, or for time of life, shall . . . sufficiently pave or cause to be paved with stone the said highway along from his or their lands or tenements adjoining to the said highway unto the midst of the same way, in such and like form as the high street between Temple Bar and Strand Cross aforesaid is paved." The penalty for neglecting to pave the street in this manner before Michaelmas 1533, and for failing to maintain the pavement afterwards, was 6d. per square yard. The next act (25 Hen. VIII., c. 8), passed in the following year," for paving of Holborn," complains of the " lack of renewing " of the pavement of the street by " the landlords which dwell not within the City." In spite of its title, this act was really applicable to the whole of the city and its suburbs. With regard to Holborn, it follows the Strand act, and then gives the mayor and aldermen power to inquire, by the oath of twelve men of the city, " as well of them that have not paved according to the provision aforesaid, as also of them that remissly or insufficiently shall hereafter maintain the same pavement or any other pavement within the said city and suburbs of the same." Any one in Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 39 default might be fined by the mayor and aldermen according to their discretions. In South wark, outside the jurisdiction of the city, the same powers were given to the justices. It was further provided that if the lessees of any lands " do sufficiently pave or repair before their mansions or dwelling-places the streets which have used to be paved, that then they and every of them shall defalk, abate, and retain in his or their own hands as much of the rents due to the lessors as they can prove to have expended on the same paving." The other eight Tudor period paving acts printed in the Statutes of the Realm all agree/in making the landlord liable, and six of them contain the provision allowing the tenants to do the work and deduct the outlay from their rents. Of the six, however, one (13 Eliz., c. 24), passed in 1571 for paving Ipswich, imposes a true money rate for defraying the expense of paving in front of parish churches, and in respect of this it fails to make any provision for a deduction from rent. The streets in front of the churches were to be paved " at the charges of the parishioners of every such church, . . . the charges thereof to be indifferently rated by the twelve head- boroughs." Returning from this digression on paving expenses, we come to an act of 1553 (i Mar., st. 2, c. 32) for repairing the causeway between Sherborne and Shaftesbury. 1 The preamble of this act says it is thought meet that the cost of putting the causeway in repair should be borne by the "owners, tenants, farmers, and inhabitants of the manors, lands, tene- 1 This act is not printed in its place in Statutes of the Realm, but it will be found recited in full in I Mar., st. 3, c. 5. 40 History of Local Rates merits, and parishes lying nigh to the said causeway and highway on either side of the same," and "the owners, tenants, farmers, and inhabitants of the towns of Shaftesbury and Sherborne." The act itself, how- ever, says the cost is to be borne by "the owners, tenants, and farmers of the lands, tenements, and hereditaments lying nigh to the said causeway and highway on either side of the same, and by the in- habitants of and within the said towns of Shaftesbury and Sherborne, and by the owners, tenants, and farmers of the manors, lands, tenements, and heredita- ments, and by the inhabitants of and within the forest of Gillingham" and certain liberties and hundreds. The justices of Somerset and Dorset are to make assessments and taxations of money or otherwise on these persons, "having good and indifferent respect to the several abilities of them and every of them." Probably no importance is to be attached to the difference in the description of the ratepayers in the preamble and the act itself. On the whole it seems probable that both the " manors " adjoining the high- way and "the owners, tenants, and farmers" of the towns of Shaftesbury and Sherborne, spoken of in the preamble, are not mentioned in the act merely because the draughtsman considered they were covered by the other expressions, "lands, tenements, and heredita- ments," and "inhabitants." The word "owners" is probably intended merely to include persons occupy- ing their own lands. Whoever was to pay, it is plain that the principle on which the payment was appor- tioned was the relative ability of the contributors. Another local highway act (i Mar., st. 3, c. 6) passed in the following year (1554) does not make the same Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 41 rather unsuccessful attempt to be explicit. It merely provides that the inhabitants of the cities of Bristol and Gloucester, with the hundreds which lie between them, shall be charged with the repair of the Glou- cester and Bristol road. It authorises the justices to rate and sess the inhabitants, but says nothing about the distribution of the burden among them. An act of 1555 (2 & 3 P. & M., c. i) "for the re- edifying of castells and forts, and for the enclosing of grounds from the borders towards and against Scotland," that is to say, in Northumberland, Cum- berland, Westmorland, and Durham, is on the model of the Sewers Acts. It authorises the appointment of a commission " to inquire by the oaths of the honest and lawful men " of the four counties, " by whom the truth may best be known, who hath or holdeth any lands or tenements or useth or perceiveth any com- mon of pasture or other profit apprender in the said counties or bishopric throughout the whole parts of the same, and all those persons and every of them or such of them, to tax, assess, charge, distrain, and pain by the number of acres and perches after the rate of every person's profit, rent, or tenure, or after the quantity of their common of pasture or profit apprender or other commodities there." Crown lands were to be liable to rating in the same way as others, and the tenants of such lands might deduct the rates from their rents. The act of 1532 for destroying crows was allowed to expire by effluxion of time ; but in 1 566 a more comprehensive act " for preservation of grain " (8 Eliz., c. 15) revived its provisions with regard to the village net, and enacted further that, in order to 4 2 History of Local Rates raise money to be paid away in rewards for the eggs and heads of birds and vermin, including foxes, the churchwardens, with six other parishioners co-opted by them, should annually, and as often as might be necessary, "tax and assess every proprietor, fanner, and other person having the possession of any land or tithes within their several parishes, to pay such sum of money as they shall think meet, according to the quantity and portion of such lands or tithes as the same person so assessed do or shall have or hold." Of course the term proprietor is here qualified by the having possession of land, so that a landlord not occupying his land would not be liable to be rated. It is only natural that a rate to be expended so directly for the benefit of agriculturists should be levied from them alone. In 1571 (by 13 Eliz., c. 18) it was enacted that the river Lea should be cleansed of all its shelves and shallows " at the costs and charges of the country," the freeholders and inhabitants being rated by the sheriffs and justices of the three counties concerned, and certain commissioners appointed by the Lord Chancellor; but this somewhat vague provision was greatly qualified by the condition that no one should be charged except in so far as he would be chargeable under the Statute of Sewers. In 1575-6 the legislature was forced to take notice of a difficulty in the enforcement of the labour required by the Highways Act, which is closely connected with the question, What constitutes an inhabitant for the purposes of rating ? The statute of 1555 was amended by an act (18 Eliz., c. 10) which, among other things, explains that persons who occupy a plough-land Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 43 divided between several parishes are to be chargeable in the parish where they dwell, and that persons who have several plough-lands, each in a different parish, are to be chargeable just as if they were resident parishioners of the parish in which each plough-land lies "in such manner and form as if he and they were a parishioner dwelling within the parishes where the same several plough-lands do lie." Curiously enough this same act contains a local provision or addendum, in which the difficulty about residence was entirely overlooked. The addendum presents several points of interest. It says : " And whereas the ferry or passage called Kingsferry within the Isle of Sheppey, in the county of Kent, before the making of the statute of highways, was usually repaired and maintained time out of memory of man at the charges of all the inhabitants and land -occupiers within the whole isle by taxation and sessment at one court or law-day time out of mind yearly holden on the Monday next after the feast of Pentecost at Kingsborough within the said isle, in the name of the Queen's Majesty and her progenitors, only for the maintenance of the same ferry ; Be it therefore enacted that the said court shall be duly kept in such manner and form as hath been heretofore accustomed, and that it shall and may be lawful to and for the jury em- pannelled and sworn at the same court for the time being, by their discretions, reasonably to assess and tax themselves and all other the inhabitants and land- occupiers of the said isle indifferently, according to the rate of land in every man's occupying, towards the maintenance of the same passage or ferry and the ways belonging or leading to the same, so as no acre of 44 History of Local Rates fresh marsh and upland be taxed above the rate of a penny in one year, nor of every ten acres of salt marsh above the rate of a penny in one year." Here we have a money rate which had been levied time out of mind for what were regarded as highway pur- poses from occupiers of land at so much per acre. Not content with reviving this ancient rate, Parlia- ment proceeded to create a similar one on the opposite side of the Swale. The road from Kingsferry to Middleton had fallen into disrepair, and the parish was not "able" to repair it. Three justices of the peace were therefore authorised "reasonably to assess and tax all and every land-occupiers dwelling out of the said isle and within four miles distant from the said ferry, as to their discretion shall seem convenient, not exceeding the sum of one penny upon every acre of fresh marsh and upland in one year, and upon every ten acres of salt marsh one penny in one year." The wording of this clause was very unfortunate, as we learn from an amending act (27 Eliz., c. 26) passed nine years afterwards, which says, " Forasmuch upon the letter of the same branch some doubt and question hath risen whether the said justices could sess any but such as be land-occupiers and dwelling out of the said isle, and within four miles distant of the said ferry ; and that thereby the taxations by them to be made by the letter of the same law will not suffice to repair the said decayed ways, for that the lands and grounds lying out of the said isle and within four miles distant of the said ferry are for the most part occupied by such persons as be inhabiting without the compass of the said four miles ; by reason whereof the said highways remain still unrepaired. ... Be it now Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 45 enacted . . . that yearly from henceforth for ever . . . it shall and may be lawful to and for six, five, four, or three justices of the peace ... to assess and tax upon all and every the lands and grounds lying and being without the said isle, and within four miles distant from the said ferry, such assessments ... as to them shall seem reasonable, notwithstanding that the owners or occupiers of the same lands or grounds be dwelling without the compass of the said four miles." This little history affords an excellent ex- ample of the insuperable difficulty involved in basing local taxation on the dwelling-place of the taxpayer. In the same year, 1584-5, was passed another act which distinctly names the abilities of the inhabitants as the criterion for the apportionment of a rate. This act, "for the Hue and Cry" (27 Eliz., c. 13), after reciting how individual inhabitants of a hundred had hitherto had no means of reimbursing themselves when their goods had been taken to pay damages to a person robbed on the highway, 1 enacts " that after exe- cution of damages by the party or parties so robbed had, it shall and may be lawful (upon complaint made 1 " And although the whole hundred where such robberies and felonies are committed, with the liberties within the precinct thereof, are by the said two former statutes charged with the answering to the party robbed his damages ; yet nevertheless the recovery and execution by and for the party or parties robbed is had against one or a very few persons of the said inhabitants, and he and they so charged have not heretofore by law had any mean or way to have any contribution of or from the residue of the said hundred ... to the great impoverishment of them against whom such recovery or execution is had." This must not be taken to prove that rates were never levied to reimburse persons whose goods had been taken in execution, but only that such persons could not compel the inhabitants to levy a rate to reimburse them. 46 History of Local Rates by the party or parties so charged) to and for two justices of the peace ... of the same county, inhabit- ing within the said hundred or near unto the same where any such execution shall be had, to assess and tax ratably and proportionably according to their dis- cretions all and every the towns, parishes, villages, and hamlets, as well of the said hundred where any such robbery shall be committed as of the liberties within the said hundred, to and towards an equal contribution to be had and made for the relief of the said inhabi- tant or inhabitants against whom the party or parties robbed before that time had his or their execution ; and that after such taxation made, the constables, con- stable, head-boroughs or head-borough of every such town, parish, village, and hamlet shall, by virtue of this present act, have full power and authority within their several limits ratably and proportionably to tax and assess according to their abilities every inhabitant and dweller in every such town, parish, village, and hamlet for and towards the payment of such taxation and assessment as shall be so made on every such town, parish, village, and hamlet as aforesaid by the said justices." This was the last rating act of importance passed before the poor-laws of 1597 and 1601 ; but as some most vital questions under the statute of 1601 re- mained unanswered till 1633, and the influence of the poor-rate is not apparent in other rating legislation before the era of the Long Parliament, the few rating acts of James L's reign may be regarded as a sort of appendix to the earlier period. Here we find in 1603-4 an act (i Jac. I., c. 31) for the relief and ordering of persons affected with the Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 47 plague. The mayor, bailiffs, head-officers, and justices of every city, borough, corporate town, or privileged place were given power " to assess all and every in- habitant and all houses of habitation, lands, tenements, and hereditaments " within their jurisdiction at " such, reasonable taxes and payments as they shall think fit." In this there seems a slight hesitation between the idea of a rate on persons and one on things. The inclusion of the things as well as the " inhabitants " is probably only due to a desire to make quite sure that non-resident occupiers should not escape. Next we have several acts of 1605-6, the third year of James I. Chapter 10, for conveying malefactors to jail, authorises "an indifferent tax or assessment" to be made by " the constables and churchwardens and two or three other the honest inhabitants of the parish, township, or tithing " where the malefactor was apprehended. Chapter 19, for repairing the highway from Non- such to Taleworth, after reciting that the parishes through which the road passes are not able to do the work, charges the expense upon the "owners, tenants, farmers, inhabitants, and occupiers of the lands, tenements, and hereditaments" lying in half- a-dozen hundreds. The apportionment was to be made "having good and indifferent respect to the several abilities, nearness, and remoteness" of the persons and property. A special provision secured the chargeability of non-residents. Chapter 20 is "for clearing the passage by water from London to and beyond the city of Oxford," and is interesting, as it contains a more general assertion of the principle of a betterment charge than any 48 History of Local Rates other act. It says, "For that it is reasonable, just, and equal that those who partake in the benefit of any good work should in fit proportion contribute to the costs and charges thereof: be it further enacted . . . that the . . . commissioners, or the more part of them, shall and may have full power and lawful authority to tax and assess such of the inhabitants of the said several counties " i.e., Oxford, Berks, Wilts, and Gloucester " as shall in their opinion be likely to receive ease or benefit by the said passage, and as well those in the said university as in the city of Oxford, at such reasonable sums of money and payments as they in their discretions shall think fit and con- venient." Eighteen years afterwards this Act was repealed and its place taken by one (21 Jac. L, c. 32) which puts the burden of improving the passage by water entirely upon the inhabitants of Oxford, on the ground that " the principal benefit thereof will redound immediately to the university and city of Oxford." The commissioners are given full power to tax and assess the inhabitants of the university and city, and also bodies politic and corporate there, as they in their discretions shall think meet. Chapter 22 of the third year of James I. is for paving Drury Lane and the town of St. Giles. It charges both the owners and occupiers of property adjoining the lane, and the inhabitants and occupiers of certain parishes. Chapter 23 autho- rises rating of the inhabitants of Monmouthshire and Gloucestershire for Chepstow Bridge. Chapter 24 recites that 700 at least had been "levied of the inhabitants of divers parts " of Worcestershire, under the Statute of Bridges, "and employed in the re-edifying of the bridge at Upton-on-Severn, so as the same, with Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 49 some small further charge, might have been perfectly finished ; notwithstanding all which, by the wilfulness of some particular persons, being unwilling to contri- bute anything towards so charitable a work, and drawing others daily to like obstinacy, whereby the inhabitants of some parts of the said county would not yield or consent to the making or levying of any taxations or assessments towards the building of the said bridge, the said good and charitable work hath been given over, so as some part of the said bridge, for that it was left unfinished, is again fallen down, and the rest greatly decayed, and like in short time to fall down unless some speedy course be taken the finishing thereof." The inhabitants of the c " other than the citizens of the city of Worcester habiting in the said city, and that only concerning the lands, goods, and chattels within the said city," are to finish the bridge within three years, on pain of a fine of 100 per annum for every year in default. The justices are empowered to " rate, tax, and assess the said county of Worcester, and the several hundreds, towns, parishes, villages, and hamlets within the same, and every inhabitant or dweller " in them, except the citizens of Worcester as provided above, and to appoint collectors. The justices had evidently been powerless to cope with a refusal on the part of the inhabitants of particular localities to assess and levy the sum rated on their district. The exemption of the citizens of Worcester only in respect of lands and goods in the city, shows the purely technical sense in which the word inhabitant was used; the situation of the property, and not that of the person, is the important thing. 50 History of Local Rates Just as in the earlier or customary rates, so in these statutory rates two principles of assessment are to be seen. The rates for sea defence, the destruction of crows and vermin, the rebuilding of Scarborough Pier, re-edification in the northern counties, the im- provement of the Lea and the Thames, are obviously intended to be assessed according to the proportion of benefit resulting from the expenditure to the rate- payers. The rates for building jails, paying members of Parliament, reimbursing persons robbed on the highway, relieving persons suffering from the plague, and conveying malefactors to jail, are equally clearly intended to be assessed according to the ability of the ratepayer. The bridges rate, too, probably belongs to the last class. Between the two classes there are some doubtful cases, such as that of the Nonsuch and Taleworth highway rate, in which the Legislature appears to halt between the two principles. In assess- ing the benefit rates, the customary method evidently was to assume that all fixed property is raised in value in equal proportion, so that it was just and expedient to levy a pound rate in respect of it upon the owner, or, in the case of recurrent expenditure, upon the occupier. In assessing the other statutory rates, the customary method must have been the same as in assessing the innumerable non- statutory rates. It was assumed that a man's ability to pay towards the local taxation of a particular place was measured by the value of the land or house he occupied. That this assumption, however, was not unquestioned in 1634 may be learnt from "the instructions and direc- tions from the Lords of the Council for the assessing and levying of the ship-money " in that year. These Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1 640 51 show us exactly where the king's advisers thought the assessment ought to differ from that of an ordinary rate, if the tax was to be as little unpopular as its unconstitutional character permitted. In the example in Rushworth, the high sheriffs of Middlesex and Hert- fordshire, and the head -officers of corporate towns therein, are commanded to provide one ship, the cost of which will be 3300, and it is suggested that Hertfordshire should pay 1500, Westminster 350, and the rest of Middlesex 1450, to make up the amount. The instructions then proceed, "Secondly, when you have settled the general assessments, we think fit that you subdivide the same, and make particular assessments in such sort as other common payments upon the county and corporate towns afore- said are most usually subdivided and assessed ; and, namely, that you, the sheriff, divide the whole charge laid upon the county into hundreds, lathes, and other divisions, and those into parishes and towns ; and the towns and parishes must be rated by the houses and lands lying within each parish and town, as is accustomed in other common payments which fall out to be payable by the county, hundreds, lathes, divisions, parishes, and towns. And whereas his Majesty takes notice that in former assessments, not- withstanding the express orders given in our letters to ease the poor that [there ?] have been assessed to- wards this service, poor cottages [cottagers ?] and others who having nothing to live on but their daily work ; which is not only a very charitable [uncharitable ?] act in itself and grievous to such people, but can admit no better instructions [construction ?] than that it was done out of an adverse humour of purpose to raise 52 History of Local Rates clamour and prejudice the service. Wherefore his Majesty's express command is that you take effectual care and order, by such precepts and warrants as you issue for this service, that no persons be assessed unto the same unless they be known to have estates in money or goods, or other means to live by over and above their daily labour; and where you find such persons to be taxed, you are to take off what shall be set upon them, and lay it upon those that are better able to bear it. And that you may the better spare such poor people, it is his Majesty's pleasure that where there shall happen to be any man [men ?] of ability, by reason of gainful trades, great stocks of money, or other usual estates, who perchance have or occupy little or no land, and consequently in an ordinary land-scot would pay nothing or very little, such men be rated and assessed according to their worth and ability; and that the monies which shall be levied upon such may be applied not only to the sparing and freeing of the such poor people as aforesaid, but also to the easing of such as, being either weak of estate, or charged with many children or great debts, or unable to bear such great charge as their lands in their occupation might require, in an usual and ordinary proportion ; and the like cause [course?] to be held by the head-officers in the corporate towns, that a poor man be not set in respect of the usual tax of his house or the like at a greater sum than others of much more wealth and ability ; and herein you are to have a more than ordi- nary care and regard, whereby to prevent complaints of inequality in the assessments, whereby we were much troubled the last year. " Thirdly, to the end that this may be effected with Miscellaneous Statutory Rates to 1640 53 more equality and expedition, you, the sheriff, are to govern yourself in the assessment for his service by such public payments as are most equal and agreeable to the inhabitants of that county ; and for your more ease and better proceeding herein, after you have accordingly rated the several hundreds, lathes, and divisions of that county, you may set forth your warrants to the constables, requiring them to call unto them some of the most discreet and sufficient men of every parish, town, or tithing, and to consider with them how the sum charged upon each hundred may be distributed and divided as aforesaid, and with most equality and indifterency ; and to return the same in writing, under their hands, with all possible expedition; which being done, you are to sign the assessment set on the several persons of every par- ticular parish, town, or tithing, if you approve thereof ; and if, for inequality, you find cause to alter the same in any part, yet after it is so altered you are to sign the same, and, keeping the true copy thereof, you may thereupon give order for the speedy collection and levying of such sums accordingly by constables of hundreds, petty constables, and others usually applied for collection of other common charges and payments." 1 It is clear from this that in 1634 it was already recognised that the ordinary method of rating was not in accordance with distribution of the burden according to ability. 1 Rush worth, Historical Collections, 1680, vol. ii. pp. 259-61. Ill POOR-LAW RATES TO l6oi WHILE the "ability" rates created by Tudor and Jacobean parliaments, in practice generally followed the model of the earlier or customary rates, and were consequently assessed in accordance with a measure- ment of ability which was no longer regarded as sound, the poor-rate, owing to its peculiar origin, started afresh direct from the principle of contribution according to ability, and was not at first encumbered with the misleading standard of the older rates. The first legislative step towards the establishment of a local rate for the relief of the poor was taken when it was enacted that certain persons dependent on charity should be confined to particular places. The act 12 Ric. II., c. 7 (1388) provided that "beggars impotent to serve shall abide in the cities and towns where they be dwelling at the time of the proclamation of this statute; and if the people of cities or other towns will not or may not suffice to find them, that then the said beggars shall draw them to other towns within the hundred, rape, or wapentake, or to the towns where they were born, within forty days after the proclamation made, and shall there con- tinually abide during their lives." A century later, in 1495, the act ii Hen. VII., c. 2, ordained "that all manner of beggars not able to work, within six weeks 54 Poor -Law Rates to 1601 55 next after proclamation made of this act go rest and abide in his hundred where he last dwelled, or there where he is best known or born, there to remain or abide, without begging out of the said hundred." The act 19 Hen. VII., c. 12 (1503-4) is rather less vague. It ordains "that all manner of beggars not able to work within six weeks next after proclamation made by this act go rest and abide in his city, town, or hundred where they were born, or else to the place where they last made their abode the space of three years, there to remain or abide, without begging out of the said city, town, hundred, or place." It also enacts that valiant vagabonds, after being punished, are to go "into such city, town, place, or hundred where they were born, or else to the place where they last made their abode by the space of three years, and that as hastily as they conveniently may, and there to remain and abide." Lastly, in 1530-1 the act 22 Hen. VIII., c. 12, provided that every impotent beggar should have a license given him by the justices, and should not go outside the limits they assigned to him, and that every able-bodied vagrant should be sent back " to the place where he was born or where he last dwelt ... by the space of three years, and there put himself to labour like as a true man ought to do." Provisions like these necessarily led to further provisions for securing that the impotent should be maintained, and the able-bodied set to work, in the places assigned to them; and so in 1535-6 we find Parliament awaking to a recognition of the fact that it was not explained " how and in what wise the said poor people and sturdy vagabonds should be ordered 56 History of Local Rates at their repair and at their coming into their countries, nor how the inhabitants of every hundred should be charged for the relief of the same poor people, nor yet for the setting and keeping in work of the aforesaid valiant vagabonds at their said repair into every hundred of this realm." 1 Difficulties had evidently arisen from the unwillingness of the "countries" or hundreds to extend charity to every impotent beggar with whom the justices saddled them, and to provide work of a kind which would satisfy the valiant vaga- bond who had been returned, like a bad shilling, to the place of his birth. A certain measure of com- pulsion was accordingly applied. It was enacted (27 Hen. VIII., c. 25) that "all the governors and ministers of every of the same cities, shires, towns, hundreds, wapentakes, lathes, rapes, ridings, tithings, hamlets, and parishes" a fine confusion of local government areas " as well within liberties as with- out, shall not only succour, find, and keep all and every of the same poor people by way of voluntary and chari- table alms, . . . but also . . . cause and compel all and every the said sturdy vagabonds and valiant beggars to be set and kept to continual labour in such wise as by their said labours they and every of them may get their own living with the continual labour of their 1 Preamble of 27 Hen. VIII., c. 25. It is curious that this act appears to assume, without any apparent justification, that the act of 1530-1 required not only able-bodied beggars and vagabonds, but also impotent poor persons, to be sent back to the place where they were born or last dwelt for three years. See the provision of 5, that leprous and bedrid persons may remain where they be, and " shall not be compelled to repair into their countries according to the tenor and purport of the aforesaid former act." There seems to have been some confusion between the act of 1530-1 and the earlier acts quoted above. Poor-Law Rates to 1601 57 own hands." Every parish in default none of the other areas are mentioned here might be fined 1 a month by quarter-sessions. In order to defray the ex- pense of succouring the impotent persons and keeping the sturdy vagabonds at work, the mayors and head- officers of corporate towns, and the churchwardens or two others of every parish, were to collect alms of the good Christian people within the same with boxes every Sunday, or otherwise, " upon pain that all and every the mayors, governors, aldermen, head-officers, and others the king's officers and ministers of every of the said cities, boroughs, towns corporate, hundreds, parishes, and hamlets, shall lose and forfeit for every month that it is omitted and undone, the sum of 20 shillings." This list of authorities seems to show that the authors of the statute had still somewhat vague notions as to the question by whom it should be put in execution. The officers of each hundred and corporate town were apparently intended to exercise a general supervision, and to distribute the " overplus " of the collections in the wealthy parishes among the poor parishes ; but the parish was the primary unit, and the provisions as to accounts all relate to it. The churchwardens, with six or four honest neighbours, could demand accounts quarterly or oftener from the collectors. The parson, or some other honest man, was to keep accounts showing receipts and expendi- ture, but the book containing them was always to remain in the custody of two or three of the con- stables and churchwardens, or some other indifferent man, by their consents, and not in that of the parson, vicar, or parish priest. The book was to be bought and paid for by the constables and churchwardens 58 History of Local Rates for the time being at the common collections, which probably means "out of the common collections." Bailiffs, constables, churchwardens, or others the collectors of alms might be paid wages out of the money collected if they forbore their own business and labour. No penalties could be exacted merely because the "voluntary and unconstrained alms and charity of the parishioners or people " who were made "contributory to such alms" turned out to be in- sufficient for the purposes of the act, and no one was to be "constrained to any such certain con- tribution but as their free wills and charities shall extend." Both these acts were repealed by the act of 1547 (i Ed. VI., c. 3), which attempts to get over the difficulty of dealing with sturdy vagabonds by making them slaves for two years, and in certain cases for life, to any man claiming them. If unclaimed by any private person, they were to be sent to the place of their birth, and there treated as public slaves. The mayors and other head -officers of every city, town, or hundred, were to see all lamed, sore, aged, and impotent persons who were born therein, or had been there most conversant or abiding by the space of three years, and who could not be treated as vagabonds, " bestowed and provided for of the tenantries, cottages, or other convenient houses to be lodged in, at the costs and charges of the said cities, boroughs, and villages, there to be relieved and cured by the devotion of the good people of the said city, borough, town, or village." Impotent poor persons found in cities and corporate towns where they were not born or had not dwelt three years, Poor-Law Rates to 1601 59 were to be sent on horseback or in carts or chariots, from constable to constable, to their place of settle- ment. 1 The meaning of the act might well have been less obscurely expressed, but it seems plain that the intention is to put the cost of housing the im- potent poor upon the public funds of the localities, which would eventually have to replenish their coffers by rates raised in the old way. The cost of main- taining the impotent poor when once housed, on the other hand, is to be defrayed by voluntary gifts. To stimulate the devotion of his flock in this respect, every parson is ordered to exhort his congregation to charity every Sunday, but there is no re-enactment of the elaborate provisions of the act of 1535-6 for enforcing and regulating the weekly collections. As any one but the legislators of the reign of Edward VI. would have expected, this slavery statute did not long remain in force. *It was repealed two years after it was passed (by 3 & 4 Ed. VI., c. 16). Its provisions for the removing, housing, and maintaining the im- potent poor, however, were re-enacted, with the ex- ception of the clause ordering the parson to exhort his congregation to charity; and the act of 1530-1 was revived, with an additional provision, which had the effect of throwing the cost of deporting destitute alien immigrants upon the ports. After two years more the provisions with regard to the collection of alms contained in the act of 1535-6 were in sub- stance restored and enlarged in 1551 (by 5 & 6 Ed. VI, c. 2): "Yearly one holiday in Whitsun week in every 1 There is no provision for removing impotent poor persons from country districts to their place of settlement. 60 History of Local Rates city, borough, and town corporate, the mayor, bailiffs, or other head-officers for the time being, and in every other parish of the country, the parson, vicar, or curate, and the churchwardens, having in a register or book as well all the names of the inhabitants and house- holders, as also the names of all such impotent aged and needy persons as ... are not able to live of themselves nor with their own labour, shall openly in the church and quietly after divine service call the said householders and inhabitants together, among whom the mayor and two of his brethren in every city, the bailiffs or other head-officers in boroughs and towns corporate, the parson, vicar, or curate, and churchwardens in every other parish, shall elect, nominate, and appoint yearly two able persons or more to be gatherers or collectors of the charitable alms of all the residue of the people for the relief of the poor, which collectors, fche Sunday next after their election (or the Sunday following if need re- quire), when the people is at the church and hath heard God's holy word, shall gently ask and demand of every man and woman what they of their charity will be contented to give weekly towards the relief of the poor ; and the same to be written in the said register or book." This public and regular contribution of definite sums promised and recorded beforehand is in itself more like a rate than the collection with boxes authorised by the act of 1535-6. It was, too, of a less voluntary character ; a person who refused to subscribe might bring down on his head ecclesiastical punishments (which were more dreaded then than now), for it was enacted that if any one " able to further Poor-Law Rates to 1 60 1 6 1 this charitable work " obstinately or frowardly refused to assist, he might be sent to the bishop, who would, "according to his discretion, take order for the re- formation thereof." These provisions remained in force till 1555, and then they were simply re-enacted almost in the same words, and stood till 1572. But important additioi were made in 1555 and 1562-3. By the act of if>5 l9 Metropolitan Board of Works, H3 Metropolitan common poor fund, 61 Middleton. See Kingsferry Mines, poor-rate on, 101 ; land-tax on, 117 ; highway-rate on, 123- 124 Minority, attempt to lay church- rate by, 1 08 Money, poor-rate on, 96-97 ; church-rate on, 107 NONSUCH to Taleworth highway, 47, 50 Norwich Cathedral poor-rate, 78- 79 ; workhouse-rate on person- alty, 89, 133 n. OXFORD rate for improving the Thames, 47-48 PAVING. See Streets Pevensey town-scot, 102-103 Plague, rate for sufferers from, 46-47, 50 Police-rate, 131 Poll-tax, 17-18 Poole, poor-rate on salaries, money, household goods, ships, and stock-in-trade, 81, 85, 96-97 ; church-rate, 107 Poor-rate, origin, 54-62 ; history to 1 60 1, 62-77 J history since 1 60 1, 78-101 ; assimilation of other rates to, 102-130 Prisoners, rate for relief of, 73-74, 109 n. Profits, 85 QUALITY of land considered, 1 1, 24 Quinzieme. See Fifteenths RAILWAYS, three-fourths exemp- tion of, 130-131 Rate-in-aid, 61, 72-73 Re-edification,. 41, 50 Rent paid, as criterion of ability, 80 ; received, not ratable, 82- 85. See Deduction Resolutions. See Judges' resolu 7 tions Ringwood poor-rate on stock-in; trade, 92-94 Roads. See Highway Rochester Bridge, 10 n. Romney Marsh, 10-12, 21-22, 28 ST. GILES paving, 48 Salaries, 24, 80-82 Scarborough pier, 35-37, 50 Scot and lot, 21 Sea-wall, 1 6. See Romney Marsh and Sewers Sewers-rate, 10-12, 21-22, 27-30, 42, 112-114 Shaftesbury and Sherborne cause- way, 39-40 Sheep, rating of, 1 6, 23 Sherborne. See Shaftesbury Ship-money, 50-53, 115 Ships, rating of, 97, 107 Shoreditch poor-rate on person- alty, 90 Soldiers, rate for relief of, 67, 74 Southampton fortifications, 17 n. 140 Index Southwark paving, 39 Status to be regarded, 79 Stock-in-trade, poor-rate on, 86- 100; church-rate on, 106-107; highway-rate on, 119-123 Strand paving, 37-38 Streets, 37, 120-121, 124-131 Subsidy, 20 n. Substance, 18, 22 Surplus from poor-rate, 65 TALEWORTH. See Nonsuch Tamworth fifteenth, 22 n. Tax distinguished from rate, 3-5 Tenths. See Fifteenths Thames, 47-48, 50 Town expenses, 17-21 Trowbridge poor-rate on per- sonalty, 96 Turnpikes, 122 UNIONS, 61, 136 Upton-on-Severn Bridge, 48-49 VAGABONDS, 55-59, 65-69, 74, 109 n., non. Visible property, 93-94, 99 WAGES. See Salaries Wales, wages of representatives in Parliament, 34-35, 50 Warminster poor-rate on person- alty, 96 Watching, 129-131 Westminster, sewers commission, 113; streets, 124-127 Whitechapel, poor-rate, 79-80 ; church-rate, 79-80, 106-107 " Will and doom," 106 Witney poor-rate on stock-in- trade, 91-92 Woods, poor-rate on, 101 ; land- tax on, 117; highway-rate on, 123-124 Worcester, not ratable for Upton Bridge, 49 ; poor-rate on per- sonalty, 89 Wrotham church-rate, 105 THE END. Printed by BALLANTYNE, HANSON & Co. Edinburgh and London RETURN TO the circulation desk of any University of California Library or to the NORTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY Bldg. 400, Richmond Field Station University of California Richmond, CA 94804-4698 ALL BOOKS MAY BE RECALLED AFTER 7 DAYS 2-month loans may be renewed by calling (510)642-6753 1-year loans may be recharged by bringing books to NRLF Renewals and recharges may be made 4 days prior to due date. DUE AS STAMPED BELOW MAR 2 6 1997 12,000(11/95) VB 06692 L