CORRIGENDA On p. 38, 2nd para., for 'French Memorandum (see pp. 29, 32)' read 'Prussian Answer to the Law Officers' Report (see p. 36) ' On p. 62, line 28, for ' President Jefferson ' read ' Mr. Jefferson, the Secretary of State,' Foot-note, for 1795 ' read ' 1799 ' Freedom of the Seat PUBLISHED FOR THE HISTORICAL SECTION OF THE FOREIGN OFFICE HE FREEDOM OF THE SEAS HISTORICALLY TREATED BY SIR FRANCIS PIGGOTT, KT. Author of " The Armed Neutralities," $c. OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS LONDON EDINBURGH GLASGOW NEW YORK TORONTO MELBOURNE CAPE TOWN BOMBAY HUMPHREY MILFORD 1919 PREFACE THERE must be some fundamental principles governing the relations of belligerents and neutral merchants; they cannot be regulated by a series of rules which have all the appearance of being haphazard, unless some recognised principle underlies them. But, even when Congresses meet for the express purpose of arriving at an agreement as to the rules, we look in vain for some statement as to what this principle is. Meanwhile, many undigested theories are advanced, based on very doubtful hypotheses. Of these the fore- most, which has taken hold of many international lawyers, is that neutral commerce with the belligerents ought not to be interfered with, but nlust be allowed to continue in war as in peace, with exception only in the case of contraband of war and trade with blockaded places. On this the alleged right, as distinguished from treaty agreement, rests that "free ships" make "free goods." There is also much insistence on the doctrine that the rules of international law are based on the common practice of nations. If this means all nations, so great is the divergence in actual practice that few rules would survive. If it means the practice of many, or the majority of nations, then, in 1780, England would have been in a minority of one, and her supremacy at sea would have passed away. Yet there must be, and is, some test of right and wrong. It is to be discovered by a study of what nations did, as belligerents and neutrals, in time of war, and testing it by the motive which lay behind ; for motive is more easily judged than action. The motives are written very plain in history: abundant war profits for the neutrals, essential assis- tance to the enemy. Belligerent action, whether it were the seizure of contraband cargoes or of ships running PREFACE ii blockade, or the larger operations of commerce-destroy- ing, has always been based on the necessity of pre- venting that assistance reaching the enemy. The standing illustration is the incessant dispute between England and France during the two years which pre- ceded the declaration of war in 1778, when the pro- fessed object of the Cabinet at Versailles was to assist the American Colonies in their rebellion. The historical method is essential to the under- standing of what, for want of a better term, is called " International Law " ; and the object of this little book is to give in outline the story of the different periods when England's action at sea was challenged by com- binations of the Neutral Powers. F. T. P. EDITORIAL NOTE THIS treatise is confined to the historical side of the question, and avoids any discussion of its controversial aspects, except in so far as these form part of its history. It is issued to the public as supplying an indispensable preliminary to the understanding of present conditions and international difficulties. . G. W. PROTHERO. TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE I. Introductory ... ... ... ... ... 1 II. The Treaty of Utrecht, 1713, and the maxim " free ships free goods " ... ... ... 14 III. The Silesian Loan, 1752-3 29 IV. The Seven Years War, 1756-63 37 V. The War of American Independence, 1776-83 ... 39 VI. The First Armed Neutrality, 1780 42 VII. The period between the First and Second Armed Neutralities ... ... ... ... ... 61 VIII. The Second Armed Neutrality, 1800 72 IX. Napoleon and "La Liberte des Mers " ... ... 81 X. Abandonment of theJArined Neutrality principles 87 * FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' HISTORICAL I INTRODUCTORY THE appropriation of the formula, the " Freedom of the Seas," by our late enemy necessitates an historical examination of its use by the enemies of Great Britain, and a renewed assertion of its true meaning. The enemy has adopted it as a comprehensive term, to deny the right of a belligerent to interfere with his free use of the sea in time of war. For a belligerent to claim free navigation and com- merce at the hands of his enemy, to assert that he is entitled to use the sea as freely in war as in peace, is to ignore the circumstances of war and practically to deny the right to tight upon the sea. But when the neutral makes this claim, the question assumes a very different and a more serious aspect ; for his assertion appears at first sight to be unanswerable. He is unconcerned with the war; a priori, therefore, he should not be affected by it, and should be allowed to continue in peaceful exercise of his rights of free navigation and commerce upon the sea. Yet this also ignores the circumstances and conditions of war ; for, obviously, free navigation and free com- merce would carry with it free intercourse with the enemy and raise the question how far this is consistent with neutrality. In the historic disputes in which England's attitude at sea has been challenged, the neutral has put forward his claim in this simple fashion; he has hardly dis- guised the fact that his aim has been to maintain free [1947] B intercourse with the enemy. The only exceptions he has been willing to admit are trade in contraband and with blockaded ports. The issue is therefore very clearly denned, and it has not varied from the time it was first raised to the present day. It must be obvious that it lies only with the neutrals to put forward this claim of free navigation. If the enemy has any right to claim it, it can only be (in the absence of a treaty) as a derivative from the neutral's right. The historical examination of the question will amply demonstrate the accuracy of this statement. Our enemy sought at the outset to cloud the issue by confusing the Laws of War with what is popularly called " International Law," and did so with some success. It is suggested that the only sound way of treating the subject is to say that the relations of belligerent and belligerent are governed by the Laws of War; that "International Law " properly applies to the relations between belligerent and neutral States; and that the questions which commonly arise in con- nection with the " Freedom of the Seas," can only be accurately defined as the relations of belligerents and neutral merchants. The point need not be laboured, but must be noticed in order to emphasise the importance of preserving an accurate nomenclature in the discussion. Confusion of meaning in the terms used has prevailed since the question was first debated, and the enemy has always availed himself of that confusion. To make my meaning clear. The question whether it is legitimate in war to destroy the commerce of the enemy can only depend on the Laws of War ; the point being whether the effect of this belligerent action does not so affect the civil population as to remove such action from legitimate warfare. The destruction cf the enemy's trade with himself his coasting trade, for example could not be condemned on any other ground. But when we come to the enemy's trade with the neutrals another factor is introduced into the discussion j the question passes fromi the sphere of the Laws of War, because other parties the neutral merchants are affected, who are unconcerned with the war. The issue then takes this form : whether those parties have commercial rights which are paramount to the right of the belligerent to annihilate his enemy. It is not easy to disentangle the two questions Whether the neutral merchant has a right to trade with the enemy? Whether the enemy has a right to trade with the neutral merchant! The discussion of the principle " free ships free goods ' is infected with this difficulty. But, war being what it is, in the absence of any support from the Laws of War, it is obvious that, if the enemy has any such right, it must be derived (in the absence of a treaty) from the right, if any, of the neutral merchant, and from the impossibility of severing the rights of the two parties to the contracts of which all commerce is composed. The argument in favour of the enemy cannot be put higher than this : that his commerce cannot be inter- fered with, because the right of the neutral merchant would also be interfered with. And this argument is no stronger than its converse the neutral merchant can have no right to trade with the enemy, because any rights which the enemy has are at the mercy of the belligerent. The solution of the difficulty either way must depend on some sounder process of reasoning. The position assumed by England may be stated very simply. Interference with neutral trade is justified whenever the premiss on which the neutral claim rests unconcern with the war is negatived by the facts. When the neutral has established relations with the enemy his claim of absolute right is vitiated. To this fundamental principle England's action has been at all times referable. It was not until the pressure of her power upon the sea became so great as prac- tically to annihilate those relations that the neutrals had recourse to the formula " Freedom of the Seas " to destroy it. The enemy followed his lead. In [1947] B 2 4 "FREEDOM OF THE SEAS " this sense and for this purpose the formula came into common use on the Continent from 1776 to 1782, at the time of the American War of Independence and the First Armed Neutrality. In this sense and for this purpose Bonaparte at the time of. the Second Armed Neutrality, in 1800, adopted it as his own. This combination of neutral and enemy, their resent- ment at the action of the Power which, used her supremacy at sea to interfere with their trading rela- tions, led to her being called the " Tyrant of the Seas," an epithet based solely on the assumption that the use of the sea in peace continues unaltered in war. Now, in the first place, war upon the sea must interfere with its free use. The quarrels of maritime nations are fought out upon the sea. There will be fighting wherever enemy ships are found (except in neutral territorial waters) ; and free navigation on the trade routes will be interrupted. Thus indirectly war diminishes the Freedom of the Seas. War also prejudices it directly; and, quite apart from the familiar questions of blockade and contra- band, free commerce is curtailed. This point must at the outset be made clear: that except indirectly, as just indicated, neutral trade with neutral is not inter- fered with, but remains "free." But it is obvious that neutral commerce alters its character directly an ultimate destination of the cargoes to the enemy is intended, and loses it altogether when it is commerce with the enemy. A new element has been introduced which entitles the belligerent to revise his admission that neutral commerce is free. This is invariably over- looked in all the statements of the case against England; interference with neutral trade with the enemy is treated as being in the same category as inter- ference with purely neutral trade with neutral. The former might be completely destroyed, and yet genuine neutral commerce remain intact. It follows, therefore, that the measure of belligerent interference with the trade of the neutrals is the nature and extent of the 5 relations which the neutrals themselves establish with the enemy. Those relations have compelled the assertion by belli- gerents of a right to visit and search neutral merchant- men in all circumstances, and of a correlative duty in the neutrals to submit to visit and search whenever it is claimed. There is in this a very direct interference with the Freedom of the Seas. Round this question all the historic disputes have centred, for the neutrals denied the duty and resisted the exercise of this right. The wars in which these disputes arose were those in which a yet larger issue was involved, a struggle for world- dominion. Of such wars England inevitably became the pivot. For, if one country hold the com- mand of the sea, so great is its influence that, even with little strength on land, it interposes an effective bar to the achievement of the ambition. Such was the position of England. By the develop- ment of sea-power, the natural resource of an island kingdom, she created from the surrounding seas the barrier of her safety. Hence the later struggles for world-dominion have involved an attempt to wrest from England the supremacy of the seas. It must be conceded that the rules of sea warfare cannot be framed to suit the exigencies of one country's position in the world. But the point involved is this: that an analysis of the history of these conflicts con- demns the principles which enemy and neutral sought to force on England, because it reveals the true motive underlying them, and shows very clearly that the principles which the neutrals proclaimed did in fact very largely concern and benefit the enemy. Not the least of these important facts is that the most vehement assertions of these principles by the neutrals have coincided with projects for the invasion of England. The foundations of the dispute were laid in the time of the Armada; it grew in strength in 1756, was further developed in 1783, and reached its zenith in 1805. History has lately repeated itself. An analysis of the principles themselves leads to the 6 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' same conclusion. The neutral claims took the form of " freedoms," whose principal characteristic was the development of an admitted truth into a fallacy favourable to the enemy. Thus, freedom of trade upon the sea became " freedom of neutral trade with the enemy." Thus also that state of quiescence which neutrality not merely enjoins, but which the security of neutral States demands, was transformed into the free- dom of the neutral flag to protect enemy property at sea, known familiarly in the form of the maxim, " free ships free goods." And so the fact that the sea is free was perverted into an all-embracing ' ' Freedom of the Seas," favourable to neutral activities of commerce with the enemy, and restricting within the narrowest limits belligerent activities to prevent it. These general statements are borne out by the out- standing fact that this spurious "Freedom of the Seas,' ' conceived by the neutrals to serve their own ends, be- came Bonaparte's catchword when he sought to destroy England's supremacy at sea as an essential preliminary to establishing it for himself, and so achieving world- dominion. The new formulas which it included would, if they had been admitted, have become effective weapons. They would have supplied him with mer- chantmen to carry his commerce in place of his own, which had been driven from the sea; the neutral flag would have saved him from the necessity of supplying them with the escort of men-of-war. The foundations of fallacy once laid, further fal- lacies, devised with the same object, came to be built upon them. Of these the most notorious were, that neutral produce should be free; that private property should be exempt from capture at sea ; that war on the sea should be conducted in the same way as war on land ; that merchant ships under convoy should be exempt from search and seizure. The acceptance of these theories by the majority of European States at different times has undoubtedly given them the appearance of being founded in justice; and they were endowed with a fictitious morality INTRODUCTORY 7 because they do, at first sight, seem to come within the scope of the true " Freedom of the Seas." If there were any substance in the contention that a widely spread recognition of a theory entitles it to rank as a principle of the Law of Nations, then undoubtedly there is a mass of evidence favourable to this theory of the neutrals. On this so-called unanimity the writers persistently dwell, and on the strength of it the Declaration of Paris was framed. The other side of the case was ignored. Of greater weight than England's consistent refusal to accept the theory is the fact that, when these neutrals went to war, they had no qualms of conscience about abandoning it. They advo- cated it only when it suited their purpose and brought them profit. English statesmanship during the great wars was specially directed to combating what were rightly called " new-fangled doctrines," to whose appearance a specific date, 1752, and to whose develop- ment a specific period, 1752 to 1815, can be assigned. The form of this treatise, which is essentially historical, does not admit of any prolonged study of the doctrines themselves; but they must be briefly examined in order to make history intelligible. The historical analysis makes this much plain : that the doc- trines had their origin in a human desire, as old as fighting itself, to make profit out of other peoples' wars. The tmder contended that " commerce " attracts to itself certain natural rights which are paramount in war. But the rights of commerce had been reduced into something like order in the thirteenth century by the Consolato del Mare, in which the claims of the neutral trader to non-interference were nicely balanced against the claims of the belligerent to non-interference. The principles worked out by the Consolato had become time-honoured through their adoption by the majority of States. The new contention involved a departure from them. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries another person forced himself prominently into notice the carrier. He, like the trader, pursued a profitable 8 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' calling, and his profits, like those of the trader, were enhanced by other peoples' wars. He also resorted to formulas to protect and develop those profits ; but in justice it must be said that it was long before he turned them into assertions of rights. He achieved his end by the more legitimate method of barter, offering some- thing in exchange for the privilege he sought to acquire ; more often than not, an alliance. In 1752 the dispute developed dangerous symptoms. Without offering the same consideration, the trader claimed the carrier's privileges as his own rights; then in process of time vendor and carrier merged into one person, the "neutral," who surrounded himself with a barrier of formulas. Finally, the enemy adopted for his own benefit all the formulas, together with all the privileges and rights they represented. They exactly fitted the neces- sities of his case ; and the analogy of a legal principle stood him in good stead. He was pur- chaser of the commodities, consignee of the cargoes; the rights of vendor and carrier, once established, enured to his benefit. There was thus established the most powerful weapon a belligerent can possess the sympathy of the neutral trader, springing from com- munity of interest. It is very necessary to appreciate one feature of the discussion which has already been hinted at. The rights were asserted as belonging to neutral nations, and were thus lifted from the plane of mere profit. But the privileges and the rights, if they existed, were to be enjoyed by individuals. Undoubtedly the resultant mass of profit benefited the in- dividual's Government, since the prosperity of the sub- ject reacts beneficially on its fiscal departments. But a clear insight into the problems raised can only be ob- tained by remembering that the actual questions in dis- pute were not national. To endow them with that quality is to eliminate the element of the human trader with which every phase of the subject abounds. At one INTRODUCTORY U stage of the dispute "the flag" was introduced, and the real issue still further obscured. On the other hand, this also must be constantly borne in mind. " Neutrality " is a state which affects Governments, not individuals. Strictly speaking, there is no such being as a " neutral person." Any duties of non-interference by individuals in war must be imposed by municipal legislation, and may vary in each State. They lie outside the province of " Inter- national Law." That law does not forbid trading by subjects of a neutral State, even in contra- band of war, with either belligerent; nor does it pro- hibit carrying the objects of that trading even in con- traband, on the sea. If there were any such law it would apply on land as well as on the sea. But carriage of commodities to one belligerent by sea is subject to a risk the risk that the other belli- gerent may seize them. Disregard of this principle characterised the Armed Neutralities; and their municipal legislation did not fulfil its promise. These, however, are abstract considerations; the point lies in their concrete application to the great struggle in which they were forced into prominence. Supremacy at sea could not be wrested from England otherwise than by fighting her at sea. Fighting at sea necessitated repairing battered ships and building new ones. The special trade with the neutrals which was essential to the enemy was in ship's timber and naval stores, in which the principal traders were Russia and the Scandinavian Powers. Thus it came about that the formulas were specially concerned with the protection of this trade, and their chief advocates were the Northern Powers of Europe. The controversy reached its climax in the Napoleonic Wars. German ambition in the late war reflected the ambition of Bonaparte. The claim of the spurious " Freedom of the Seas," and of all the old formulas included in it, was revived to serve the old purpose the destruction of the great impediment to world- dominion, England's supremacy at sea. 10 ' FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' The following quotations from German writers dur- ing the war state quite frankly German aims: ' What do we Germans understand by freedom of the seas ? Of course, we do not mean by it that free use of the sea which is the common privilege of all nations in time of peace, the right to the open highways of international trade. That sort of freedom we had before the war. What we understand to- day by this doctrine is that Germany should possess such maritime territories, and such naval bases, that at the out- break of a war we should be able, with our navy ready, reason- ably to guarantee ourselves the command of the seas. We want such a jumping-off place for our navy as would give us a fair chance of dominating the seas, and of being free of the seas during a war. The inalienable possession of the Belgian seaboard is therefore a matter of life and death to us, and the man is a traitor who would faint-heartedly relinquish this coast to England. Our aim should be not only to keep what our arms have already won on this coast, but sooner or later to extend our seaboard to the south of the Strait of Calais." This statement was made by Count Reventlow at a public meeting in Berlin in March 1917, and was afterwards quoted by Lord Robert Cecil in the House of Commons. An attempt was made to attribute it to the German Navy League only, but there is no doubt that it expresses views widely held in Germany, and enjoying at least semi-official approval, which are to be found in many other similar statements in the public press. The following are typical examples : From an article in the semi-official monthly, Ueberall, by Lieut. -Commander Bierbrauer zu Brenn- stein, towards the end of 1917: " For Germany there is only one ' freedom of the seas,' which is the liberation of the seas from the tyranny of England. England's outrageous power must be broken for ever. To achieve this end a strong and mighty Germany is required, and then the seas will be free. To achieve this a strong and powerful German navy is also required. We must have defended naval bases in our colonies and also on the Belgian coast, where no Englishman may land with hostile intent. Germany will then be the real protector of the neutrals and of the freedom of the seas. It must and shall be so. ' ' INTRODUCTORY 11 From an article by Herr Winand Engel in the Pan- German organ, Das Grossere Deutschland: " German policy is forced, to secure for itself by all con- ceivable means domination over the world-sea. I deliberately . use the expression ' domination over the world- sea ' and not the expression ' freedom of the seas,' which is common to-day. The latter expression is either dishonest or stupid. The sea is free to us only if we dominate it. If we do not dominate it, it may one day be closed against us." , ' i . . ' 5 ' : These statements breathe the same spirit as Bonaparte's fiery utterances. The " Freedom of the Seas " is explained to mean something which would enable Germany to obtain certain strategic advantages and improve her position as a maritime Power. But the nature of these strategic advantages the naval bases demanded; the use to which they would be put (" jumping-off places" for the navy) reveal very clearly the ulterior object of the claim. The German object in claiming the " Freedom of the Seas " does not differ from Bonaparte's to destroy England's com- mand of the sea, and to obtain the command as the essential factor of world-dominion. This is the mili- tary aspect of the question; the commercial aspect, as it is derived from history, is dealt with in outline in this, essay. For Bonaparte it was another means of achieving the same object, and the doctrines he advanced have been advanced by the Germans. It may be summarised in one short sentence to utilise the neutral. The aim of the neutral was to trade with the enemy with greater freedom from England's belligerent inter- ference. The aim of the enemy was to trade with the neutral with the same freedom, because that trade would assure his supplies of ships' timber and naval stores, without which he could not carry on the war. This was as true of the war carried on by Louis XVI as it was of the Napoleonic Wars. Bona- parte's principle was that as against England no nation had a right to be neutral; and the " Continental System " was built up by the use he made of unwilling 12 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' neutrals, compelling them to refuse to trade with Eng- land. Louis XVI's Minister, de Vergennes. also devised a Continental System by the law of July, 1778. He promised the neutrals " free ships free goods," on condition that they would compel England to recognise the principle. He withdrew the favour from the Dutch, until they were forced to insist on a one-sided interpretation of the Treaty of Westminster of 1674, which led them into war with England. In both cases " free ships free goods " was the strategic formula by which, under the guise of " free com- merce," world-dominion was to be obtained. As Mahan says, the neutral carrier " was the key of the position." 1 The broad principle on which England's action against the neutrals has been based is to prevent their assistance in any form reaching the enemy, whether that assistance took the form of carrying the enemy's coasting trade, assisting him in carrying on his colonial trade, carrying the enemy's goods to his ports, 'or creating a shore depot through wnich goods passed to the enemy overland. The subsidiary points specially dwelt on in this essay are: (i) that treaties do not, as a rule, establish general principles of International Law; the enjoy- ment of the privileges created by them are limited to the parties who have entered into them; (ii) that the trade by which assistance is rendered to the enemy is carried on by individual merchants and shipowners, and not by neutral States; (iii) that the laws of neutrality affect Governments, not individuals; and although attempts have often been made to prohibit trade with the enemy, even in contraband, or with blockaded ports, the trading instinct is so strong that they have failed There is no other solution of the difficulty than the recognition of the fact that this trade is carried on subject to the risk of seizure by the belligerent. So much emphasis has been laid by the Germans on 1 Influence of Sea Power upon the French Revolution and .Empire, Vol. II., p. 354. INTRODUCTORY 13 the breach of neutrality which they allege to be involved in supplying contraband to the belligerents, that it may be well to point out that, if trade in con- traband were prohibited by law, it would lead to this inevitable result that all States would be compelled to fight on their own resources, and", inevitably, the small States would be rapidly absorbed by a powerful State bent on achieving world-dominion. Exigencies of space prevent this essay from being as complete as it should be. There are at least three important questions in the history of the subject which it has been impossible to elaborate: (i) the policy of Louis XVI in 1778, which led to the passing of the law of July, in which " free ships free goods " was first adopted; (ii) the maritime law of France; and (iii.) the general scheme of the old commercial treaties in which the maxim "free ships free goods" was agreed to between the parties to them as a corollary to their acceptance of " enemy ships enemy goods." II THE TREATY OF UTRECHT, 1713, AND THE MAXIM '" FREE SHIPS FREE GOODS " IN March, 1812, the Due de Bassano, Minister of Foreign Affairs, presented a Report to Bonaparte, which was read before the Senat-Conservateur of the Empire. It began with the following sentences : " Sire, Les droits maritimes des neutres ont ete regies solennelle- ment par le traite d'Utrecht, devenu la loi commune des nations. Cette loi, textuellement renouvelee dans tous les traites subsequents, a consacre les principes que je vais ex- poser. Le pavilion couvre la marchandise. La marchandise eniiemie sous pavilion neutre est neutre, comme la mar chandise neutre sous pavilion ennemi est ennemie. " Les seules marchandises que ne couvre pas le pavilion, sont les marchandises de contrebande, et les seules mar- chandises de contrebande sont les armes et les munitions de guerre. ***** The Report is based on this thesis: the Berlin and Milan Decrees must remain in force until the English Orders in Council are withdrawn, and the principles of the Treaty of Utrecht regarding neutrals are restored to validity (remis en mgueur). England is to be banished from the Continent until she consents "finally to adopt the principles on which European society is based, to recognise the Law of Nations, and to respect the rights consecrated by the Treaty of Utrecht. ' ' England's many offences were recited in the pre- amble to the Berlin Decree, but her crowning iniquity, in the eyes of the enemy, was the declaration of blockade of the coasts from the River Elbe to the Port TREATY OF UTRECHT 15 of Brest on May 16, 1806. The Due de Bassano con- tinued : " Ce fut en 1806 que commenca 1'execution de ce systeme, qui tendait a faire flechir la loi commune des nations devant les ordres du Conseil et les reglements de l'Amiraut6 de Londres. Le Gouvernement anglais arrachait ainsi le masque dont il avait couvert ses projets, proclamait la domination universelle des mers, regardait tous les peuples comme ses tributaires, et imposait au continent les frais de la guerre qu'il entretenait centre lui. Ces mesures inou'ies exciterent une indignation generale parmi les Puissances qui avaient conserve le senti- ment de leur independance et de leurs droits." This Report forms a convenient starting-point for the consideration of the historical aspect of the " Free- dom of the Seas." It states, as no other document, in the most concise form, the nature of the long-standing grievance against England. In reality it is the griev- ance of the neutrals; it is here adopted by the enemy. Moreover, it puts the case of the neutrals as high as it can be put: that it rests on treaty, the treaty of 1713, by which the political system of Europe had been adjusted. If the neutrals could be persuaded to believe that the Law of Nations had also been settled at the same time, England's dominion over the seas would be shown to be based on the breach of this fundamental treaty ; they would then the more easily be persuaded to try to shake themselves free from her domination, and Bonaparte would have gone a long way to establishing that " Free- dom of the Seas " of which he claimed to be the pro- tector. But, if the case against England as put by Bonaparte breaks down, it is certain that the neutrals can find no more powerful advocate, nor any stronger argument. Now. first, the Report starts with a distorted state- ment of fact. The notification of the blockade of the Elbe was itself a reprisal for the closing by Prussia, at the instigation of Bonaparte, of the North Sea ports against British shipping on 1st April, 1806. 1 1 Cambridge Modern History, Vol. IX., pp. 364, 365. 16 'FREEDOM OF THE SEAS" Secondly, the Report is based on a fallacy. A treaty has no larger effect than the parties themselves propose to give to its provisions. It binds those who make it and those who adhere to it, but no others. And what is true of one treaty between many parties is equally true of any number of identical treaties. Although, there- fore, the observance of a treaty, like the fulfilment of any other agreement made by States, is rightly said to be required by the Law of Nations, the provisions of a treaty have no claim to be regarded as principles of that law. It was boldly asserted by the Prussian lawyers in the Silesian Loan dispute that treaties of maritime nations are evidence of the Law of Nations. I doubt if so crude a statement is ever now made; a more insidious argu- ment has taken its place. It is contended that, where the same provision is found in many treaties, this shows that the trend of opinion among the nations is favour- able to that provision, and that this is practically equivalent to its adoption as a principle of Inter national Law. But this contention is completely answered by history. Many treaties, almost identical in their provisions, were concluded at the time of the First Armed Neutrality. Not only did England decline to admit that they were principles of International Law, .but the parties to them found them so unpractical when they were themselves belligerent, that within a few years they all had abandoned them. The Report is also inaccurate in another statement of fact. The " Treaty of Utrecht " did not fulfil any condition, real or imaginary, which justified the Due de Bassano's assertion that it became, or was ever intended to become, the " common law of .nations." It is no more than a convenient historical expression used to indicate all the treaties by which the War of the Spanish Succes- sion was brought to an end in 1713. There were sepa- rate treaties between England, Prussia, Holland. Savoy, and Portugal on the one hand, and France and Spain on the other. These were treaties of peace, with TREATY OF UTRECHT 17 which we ha.ve no concern. There were also commer- cial treaties between England and France, England and Spain, France and Holland, Spain and Holland, France and Savoy, and Spain and Portugal. Only the first three dealt with trade between neutrals and the enemy. According to the Due de.Bassano, therefore, the " common law of nations " depends on the identity of principles adopted in these three treaties. Yet even this does not exhaust the fallacies witli which the subject is surrounded. It is very commonly asserted that, by the Commercial Treaty of Utrecht between England and France, England "accepted" the doctrine that free ships make free goods. If this were true, the hostile criticism of England's attitude would be amply justified. It is essential, therefore, once and for all, to get at the true facts of the case. A brief study of the meaning of the doctrine will be necessary, because the assertion that enemy property ought to be, and therefore is, exempt from capture on board neutral ships, is woven into every phase of the history of England's disputes with the neutrals, and is the cardinal principle on which rests the spurious "Freedom of the Seas." All the subtleties involved in its gradual rise to its present prominence must be studied quite apart from the fact that it was included in the Declaration of Paris. Now, first, it is a treaty formula, and nothing else. In spite of all that has been alleged to the contrary, the principle involved in the formula is not, and never has been, a principle of International Law. The laws of no State recognised it prior to the French law of July 1778, but, on the contrary, the laws of all maritime States empowered their cruisers to seize enemy pro- perty on neutral ships. On the very threshold of the enquiry, moreover, we are confronted w r ith a difficulty. For the practical purpose of appreciating what the consequences of the maxim would be in war, it would seem essential to be familiar with the wording of the clauses embodying it. In no other way can we ascertain to whom the privilege [1947] C 18 "FREEDOM OF THE SEAS 11 has been granted, and in what circumstances it may be exercised. Nowhere so far as I have been able to trace has the form in which the maxim is commonly introduced in the treaties been fully considered and properly emphasised. It is to this effect : if one of the two contracting parties is at war with a third State, then the other, remaining neutral, may trade freely with the enemy, and may even carry his goods free. To take a concrete case. Suppose a treaty between Holland and Peru contained this clause: then, if Peru were at war with Bolivia, Holland might carry Bolivian goods free ; or, if Holland were at war with Bolivia, Peru might do the same. Obviously this is a very limited adoption of the principle, for the case of war between Holland and Peru does not come within the scope of the arrangement. If the principle were agreed to in such a case, the language of the clause would run somewhat as follows " If the two contracting parties are at war with each other (which God forbid), then the goods of each may be carried on neutral vessels without inter- ference from the other." The consequences resulting from these two forms are radically different. By the first, the right to carry free is granted to one neutral only. The enemy, the " third State ' ' with which one of the parties may be at war. will only have a very limited right to " free " carriage for his goods. By the second, free carriage by all neutrals would be conceded to the potential enemy, and thus, through him, the privilege would be acquired by all neutrals. There are so many treaties in which the principle is introduced, that I hesitate to make the positive state- ment that this second form does not exist in any of them. It is almost certain, however, that it is not to be found in any treaty prior to the Armed Neutrality Conventions. It was introduced into them in circum- stances which are explained in this treatise, and also in many concluded under its inspiration between 1780 arid 1800. These conventions were intended to have a collective operation ; and the agreement in them TREATY OF UTRECHT 19 took the form of a definite statement of principle to which the several Powers adhered : that free ships make free goods. Presumably, therefore, it should have applied in the case of war between any of the adhering Powers, a presumption unfortunately not borne out by facts. Between 1800 and 1856 the practice of indepen- dent treaties between two States was reverted to ; and it is during this period that the second form of the clause, if it exists at all, will be found. In 1856, with the signing of the Declaration of Paris, the ques- tion entered another phase. This brief survey made of a very complicated sub- ject, we may now enquire what warrant there is for any of the current statements with regard to the posi- tion of England after the Commercial Treaty of Utrecht with France. Article XVII runs as follows : ' II sera libre a tons les sujets de la reine de la Grande- Bretagne et du roi T. C. de naviguer avec leurs navires en toute liberte et securite, et sans distinction relative au pro- prietaire des marchandises qui y sont chargees, d'un port quel- conque vers un endroit appartenant aux ennemis du roi T. C. ou de la reine de la Grande -Bretagne. II sera de meme permis aux susdits sujets et habitans de naviguer avec lesdites mar- chandises et les navires en toute liberte^ et securite des endroits, ports et stations des ennemis des deux parties ou de 1'une d'elles, et cela sans aucune contradiction ni empechement, non seulement directement des susdits endroits hostiles a un endroit neutre, mais aussi d'un endroit hostile a un autre, qu'ils soient sous la juridiction du meme prince ou sous diffe'rentes juridictions. " Et, comme il a de"ja e"te stipule, a 1'^gard des navires et de& marchandises, qu'un vaisseau libre rende aussi libre la marchandise, et qu'on regarde comme libre tout ce qui sera trouve charge" sur les navires appartenant aux sujets de 1'autre partie contractante, quand rneme la totalit^ de la cargai&on ou une partie d'icelle appartiendroit aux ennemis de 1'une ou 1'autre majest^s, a 1'exception toutefois des marchandises de contrebande, il a e'te' convenu de meme que cette liberte s'^tendra aussi aux personnes qui se trouvent sur un navire libre; de telle sorte que quand meme elles sont ennemies des deux parties ou de 1'une d'elles, elles ne seront pas enleve"es du vaisseau libre, a moins qu 'elles ne soient militaires et au service de 1'ennemi." [1947] C '2 20 * FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' By Article XVIII contraband was excepted from the application of Article XVII. The provisions of this article are three. First, if one of the parties should be at war, the subjects of the other party may continue their commerce freely, irrespective of the ownership of the cargo, even to enemy ports. ' ' Free ships free goods ' ' is not accepted in so many words ; nor is. it to be derived from a provision very common in the early treaties allowing free commerce with the enemy. It is the necessary inference from the recognition of a right of free navigation irrespective of the ownership of the cargo. Secondly, the principle is repeated and reinforced: this trade may be carried on, not only irrespective of the ownership of the cargo, but also irrespective of the ports of departure or destination, even though both may be enemy ports. In other words, the subjects of the party not at war may trade between the ports of the enemy of the other party. The principle is ex- tended to wars in which the two parties are engaged with a common enemy. Thirdly, the principle of " free cargoes " is extended to enemy subjects on board vessels belonging to the other party. Unless they are soldiers in the enemy's service, they are to be free persons. But this third provision is stated in a long and complicated paragraph in which there is an express reference to " free ships free goods," and it is this paragraph which has given rise to much misconception. It is assumed that it condenses into this formula the effect of the first part of the article. In order to understand this paragraph it is neoes- sarv to examine the earlier treaties between France and England. In the Treatv of Westminster, concluded between Cromwell and Louis XIV in 1655, the question was dealt with very superficially in the following articles: " XV. That for the space of four years to come, or until other stipulations are agreed on, the ships of either nation may carry commodities of any kind to the enemies of the other, excepting to places besieged, and excepting military stores, in which cases they shall be deemed lawful prize." TREATY OF UTRECHT 21 " XXII. Either party may traffick freely to any country at war with the other, observing the stipulations of the fifteenth article, in relation to contraband and places besieged." In the Treaty of St. Germain-en-Laye, however, in 1677, the subject is dealt with in a much more elaborate manner. The articles are very complicated, because the case of each of the contracting parties is dealt with separately. Article I lays down the general principle of freedom of commerce carried on by the subjects of each country with all countries in peace or neutrality, without molestation on pretext of war between the other party and those countries. The words used are "naviguer, negocier, et faire toute sorte de trafic " ; and they are specifically explained to mean that, with the exception of contraband, traffic in war is to con- tinue as in peace. Whatever might be the interpretation of this article if it stood alone, its meaning is explained in Article VIII, which will be more easily understood by taking the concrete case of war between France and, say, Holland, England remaining neutral. The principles, and the only principles, laid down are these: (a) That English goods on Dutch [or French] ships may be seized : affirming " enemy ships enemy goods " ; " et au contraire " (b) That Dutch [or French] goods on English ships may not be seized : affirming " free ships free goods." The article then proceeds to deal with the case of a " new war," and declares that it seeks to prevent such a war, in which one of the parties may become engaged, from doing harm to the subjects of the party remain- ing at peace. The seizure of an enemy ship laden with the goods of subjects of this party is not to render the goods liable to confiscation if they are laden within a certain period after the outbreak of war, the principle " enemy ships enemy goods " being thus suspended for a time. The acceptance by England of principles entirely at variance with her ancient maritime law is at first sight 22 ' FEEEDOM OF THE SEAS ' startling. In order to understand the reason we must first appreciate the extreme severity of French mari- time law towards neutrals. Not only were enemy goods seized on neutral ships, but the ships themselves were confiscated in virtue of the Ordinance of 1681. Also neutral goods were seized on enemy ships. The position then before the Treaty of St. Germain- en-Laye was that both France land England seized enemy goods on neutral ships, but France seized the neutral ships as well. She also seized neutral goods on enemy ships, while England restored them, only confiscating the vessel. But after the treaty, although the general laws of both countries remained unaltered, in wars in which one of the two countries was engaged, the other remaining neutral, both countries seized that neutral's goods on enemy ships, and both released enemy goods on that neutral's ships. Both countries, therefore, for this limited purpose, accepted " free ships free goods"; but, in doing so, France made a greater change than England, for she gave up the seizure of neutral ships which had enemy goods on board. The result was that, when France went to war, English neutral ships were freed from confiscation when carrying enemy goods. It was a concession for which a price was paid: enemy goods themselves were freed. Yet even this does not explain the radical change in the law reciprocally agreed to in this treaty; for France also gave up the confiscation of enemy goods on neutral ships when they were English. We may legitimately assume that France would not have abandoned her ancient practice without a quid pro quo. The inference is clear: England's acquiescence in "enemy ships enemy. goods" was the consideration for the benefit- obtained in favour of English ships. This view is supported by Schoell and Reddie. This principle is so foreign to English principles of maritime law that a brief space must be devoted to it. The justification for its adoption is that it checks one form of assistance to the enemy; the reason for it is TREATY OF UTRECHT 23 that the enemy flag does prima facie impart its quality to the goods on board. But, this once admitted, it would follow that the neutral flag should also impart its quality to the goods laden under it; and thus the adop- tion of " free ships free goods " logically followed, the justification being the mutual trade advantages derived from it. It was an arrangement by which a war in which one* party should be engaged was prevented " from doing harm to the subjects of the party remaining at peace." Henceforward, therefore, the principle that the flag governed seizures was estab- lished between the two countries when one of them was at war with another Power. This explanation inverts the usually accepted order of evolution of the two maxims, but it affords a solid reason for, and explanation of, the changes in the law of France in favour of English ships : the reciprocal adoption by both countries of a new principle of seizure, from which, while both would lose in some circumstances, both would profit in others. Moreover, it fits in with the sequence of the maxims as dealt with in Article VIII, and the use of the words " et au con- traire " (p. 21), in introducing " free ships free goods." This distinct trace of a natural evolution eliminates from "free ships free goods" the humanitarianism which has been appealed to in support of it at a later period. It also eliminates any general idea of com- mercialism in the sense of benefiting the neutral. It substitutes very substantial but reciprocal commercial advantages to the parties to the treaty. The provisions of this Treaty of Utrecht now be- come intelligible. First, they are no more than a re- newal of the provisions of Article VIII of the Treaty of St. Germain-en-Laye, the first part of Article XVII being almost identical with the earlier article. They were in need of renewal on account of the revival in 1704 (during the Spanish Succession War) of the French Ordinance of 1681. The settlement of out- standing commercial questions at Utrecht was made 24 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' the occasion for adjusting the difficulty and reaffirming the provisions of the Treaty of St. Germain-en-Laye. Secondly, the principle "enemy ships enemy goods" was also reaffirmed at Utrecht, a point which the com- mentators invariably overlook. Finally, the words " Et, comme il a deja ete stipule " explain themselves; they refer to the introduction of ' ' free ships free goods ' ' into the Treaty of 1677, and not to its reaffirmation in the first, part of the article. The object of the second part of the article was merely to extend tjie principle of " free goods " to " free persons " on board enemy ships. 1 It is impossible that the second part should refer to the first part of the article, because it recites a pro- vision which is not contained in it : " Et, comme il a deja ete stipule, a 1'egard des navires et des marchandises, qu'un vaisseau libre rende aussi libre la mar- chandise, et qu'on regarde comme libre tout ce qui sera trouve charge sur les navires appartenant aux sujets de 1'autre partie contract-ante, quand meme la totalite de la cargaison ou une partie d'icelle appartiendroit aux ennemis de 1'une ou 1'autre majestes. ..." There are similar though not identical stipulations in Article VIII of the treatv of 1677 "bien que les dites marchandises fissent la meilleure partie de la charge entiere des dits vaisseaux." The meaning of that is that free ships are to make free goods, even though the greater part of the cargo belongs to the 1 It is necessary to notice a curious and most misleading mistranslation of the French text in the English official version of the treaty, which is printed in Chalmers' Collection, and repro- duced by Eeddie. The sentence beginning " Et, comme il a de'ja ete stipule . . ."is rendered, " And it is now stipulated con- cerning ships and goods, that free ships shall give a freedom to goods. . ." This version of the article has undoubtedly given rise to the statement above referred to, that England adopted the maxim in the Treaty of Utrecht; and all the criticisms of her subsequent action in regard to the maxim are clearly based upon it. It is sufficient to point out that the words themselves, " comme il a deja e"te stipule," show that the principle was not accepted then, but had already deja been agreed to. It is further to be noted that the treaty is bilingual, both the Latin and French texts being joint originals. TREATY OF UTRECHT 25 enemy. The meaning of the reference in the Treaty of Utrecht is that free ships make free goods if the whole or even a part of the cargo belongs to the enemy. Can this discrepancy in the reference be explained ? It can only be a verbal discrepancy, because it is not possible to construe the earlier provision to mean that the ship is to impart its freedom to the goods if, say, seven-eighths, but not the whole cargo, is enemy; and, therefore, the existence of variable texts of the treaty of 1677 might possibly furnish the reason. The more probable explanation, however, is that the proceedings of the French during the war, especially the re-enact- ment of the law of 1681, had aroused suspicions; and that, therefore, a paraphrase, intended to remove any doujb't as to the meaning of the earlier provision, was introduced into the Treaty of Utrecht. The result of this somewhat elaborate analysis of Article XVII of the Treaty of Utrecht may now be summarised. It disposes of the contention that England adopted in that treaty the novel principle in her wars that the neutral flag covers enemy cargoes. 1 It refers that adoption to a much earlier period. But in regard to this adoption it established these facts ; first, that it was for a very definite purpose to relieve English vessels when neutral in French wars from the severity of French maritime law. It was therefore limited in its scope and intention to France. Secondly, it was not adopted by England alone, but also by France. Quite apart from the reason for the change, there was a reciprocal concession for a reciprocal advantage. Thirdly, this re- ciprocal arrangement was not merely that the neutral flag should cover enemy's goods, but that "the flag" should cover the cargo in all cases; if the flag was enemy, then the goods were to be considered enemy ; if neutral, then the goods were to be considered neutral. 1 See Cambridge Modern History, Vol. V., p. 443. 26 ' FREEDOM OF THE SEAS " But this leads to a more far-reaching conclusion. Of the maxim, " free ships free goods," Pitt declared that, when granted, it was as a matter of favour, not as of right. Fox, when he justified his offer to Catherine, in 1782, to accept the principle, declared that he in- tended to get something in return an alliance with Russia, of which we then stood greatly in need. 1 In the foregoing analysis of our agreement with France the something that we obtained in return has been made clear ; it was a material alteration of the French law in favour of our ships. And so it is in all the other cases in which we have accepted the maxim in a treaty. Nowhere is there to be found a bald accept- ance of the principle. It is accepted reciprocally in treaties of commercial alliance; that is, in treaties concluded under the influence of a desire by both parties to obtain reciprocal commercial advantages. Commercial alliances, however, are often intimately connected with political alliances ; and in every other case in which England has accepted the maxim a political alliance has been close at hand. This hardly needs emphasising in the case of the Dutch. The manifest advantage conceded, after many years of strenuous diplomacy, to the great carrying nation in 1674 was compensated by the specific agree- ment of 1678 for mutual succour in the event of either party being attacked. In the case of Spain the commercial treaty was made in 1667, and was confirmed by the treaty of alliance in 1670. In the case of Portugal the first commercial treaty was concluded in 1642 ; but this was replaced by the treaty of 1654, which was a treaty of peace and alliance. This, then, is the first fact to be appreciated in regard to the appearance of the maxim in the English treaties. But there is another of equal importance, which enables us to get to closer grips with the Due de 1 March .25, 1801 (Hansard, Parl. Hist., Vol. xxxv, Col. 1127 et seq.) TREATY OF UTRECHT 27 Bassano's statement that the "common law of nations " was established at Utrecht. A commercial treaty was also concluded in 1713, between France and Holland, in which the principle of the flag was accepted. It existed in the old treaty between England and Holland. Therefore these three countries, England, France, and Holland, severally agreed that, whenever there was a war between any two of them, the flag of the third, remaining neutral, should protect the property of either belligerent from seizure by the other. The consequences of this will be made clearer by taking concrete cases : (a) England at war with Holland: Dutch goods on French ships would be free under the Anglo-French treaty, English goods on French ships would be free under the Franco-Dutch treaty. (b) England at war with France : French goods on Dutch ships would be free under the Anglo-Dutch treaty; English goods on Dutch ships would be free under the Franco-Dutch treaty. (c) France at war with Holland : French goods on English ships would be free under the Anglo-Dutch treaty; Dutch goods on English ships would be free under the Anglo-French treaty. The freedom of enemy goods on neutral ships in any of these several wars would extend no further than as here stated, for the plain reason that the treaty stipu- lations warrant no more extended modification of the practice. Again concrete cases will make this intelli- gible: If England were at war with Holland, neither Dutch nor English goods would be free on Russian ships ; nor, if England were at war with France, would French or English goods be free on Bremen ships ; nor, if France were at war with Holland, would French or Dutch goods be free on Danish ships; for in none of these cases is there a treaty to support the claim. 28 l FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' Two things are thus made abundantly clear. Firstly, that, in the common form in which " free ships free goods" is accepted in the treaties, its application is strictly limited to the specific case provide. 'tit. ii, 254. [1947]' F 2 68 : FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' seas." In November, Bonaparte overthrew the Govern- ment and became First Consul. The relations between Great Britain and the newly- born United States of America during the beginning of the French wars form a separate subject. The activities of the new American mercantile marine were specially directed to trade with the French West Indian Colonies; and, carrying on the tradition of the Seven Years' War, the "Rule of 1756" became, at the outbreak of war in 1793, the basis of the Instructions to the British Fleet. A vigorous attack was made on the French colonial trade, the result of which was that a great number of American ships were seized and condemned. The Instructions of June, 1793, did no more than authorise the detention of all ships laden wholly or in part with corn, flour, or meal, bound to any port in France, or any port occupied by the armies of France. The ships were to be sent to a convenient port where the cargoes would be purchased by the British Govern- ment, and the ships released after a due allowance for freight had been made out of the proceeds of the cargo. In November of the same year, however, Additional Instructions were issued, under which " all ships laden with goods the produce of any colony belonging to France, or carrying provisions or other supplies for the use of any such colony," were to be seized and brought in for lawful adjudication. This amounted to a restatement of the Rule of 1756. The merchants of the United States were the first, and by far the most enterprising adventurers in the new field that was opened to neutrals in the Antilles ; and the ports of the French islands were speedily crowded with their vessels. The United States pro- tested, and fresh Instructions were issued in January, 1794, under which the seizures were limited to vessels laden with produce of the French West Indies, " and coming directly from any port of the said islands to any port in Europe." When the goods were the PEttlOD BETWEEN 1783-1800 69 property of French subjects, they were to be seized, to whatever ports they might be bound. In order to appreciate the concession made by the new Instructions, it is necessary to bear in mind the point made in the Introductory .Remarks, that a claim to "free commerce with the enemy " differs essentially from a claim to "free commerce" pure and simple; and that the maintenance of the latter is perfectly consistent with the destruction of the former. There was a genuine market for the West Indian produce in the l/nited States, especially coffee. It was never the policy of England to interfere with purely neutral trade; such interference could not be justified in any circumstances. This American trade with the French colonies was, however, not neutral trade with neutral; it was trade with the enemy; but it was for neutral consumption, and, in order to preserve good relations with the Americans, the concession was made. The Instructions must be studied in the light of the truism, that a belligerent is not bound to have recourse to his full power at any time, or at all, during a war ; therefore, what he may do is not necessarily to be judged by what he actually does. Some powers may be held in reserve ; the exercise of extreme rights may be waived. The issue of the Instructions of 1794 is not, therefore, to be construed into an admission that the American protest against those of November 1793 was justified. It was a concession, and nothing more. At this point the difficulties in the relations between Great Britain and the United States began to be intensified, and what came to be called at the time ' Frauds of the Neutral Flag " developed rapidly. The second provision of the Instructions maintained the traditional principle of belligerency the seizure of enemy property on neutral ships. We have it on the testimony of James Stephen, who wrote in 1805, that " it was evident that the flag of the United States was, for the most part, used to protect the property of the French planter, not for the American merchant." 1 1 " War in Disguise; or, the Frauds of the Neutral Flag " (1917 Ed.), p. 19. 70 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' This was, however, only one method of evading the British cruisers which the connivance of the neutral trader suggested. The concession itself was full of commercial potentialities which the American traders were quick to seize. Coffee and other colonial produce were in as great demand in Europe as ;in .the States ; they could be imported freely into the United States; they were simply re-exported to France and the Continent, " the broken voyage being considered to purge the origin of the commodities." Mahan says that,-" debarred from going with it direct to Europe by the Rule of 1756, the rise in price, due to diminished production and decrease of transport, allowed them to take the sugar and coffee of the. colonies at war .with England to American ports, re-ship it to the Continent, and yet make a good profit on the transaction." This was the germ of that devious method of getting cargoes to the enemy which was subsequently developed to such an extent as to lead the Prize Court .to enunciate the doctrine of "continuous voyage," of which, a few years later, we were to hear so much. The friction between the two countries having become acute, the United States proposed their adjustment by treaty; and John Jay was sent as envoy to England. The treaty, concluded in November 1794, was not ratified till October 1795. American ships had, by the Instructions of January 1794, the privilege of direct trade between their own country and the British East and West Indies, but they were precluded from carry- ing the produce of those colonies to other foreign ports. A provision had been introduced into Art. XII of the treaty, which would have stopped the practice of the broken voyage by which thev sought to evade the effect of the Instructions; but the Senate rejected it, and the treaty was ratified without it. In 1798 fresh Instructions were issued, and a further concession was made. Vessels laden with the produce of enemy colonies were to be seized "coming directlv from any port of the said islands or settlements to any 1 Mahan, op. cit., Vol. II, p. 253. PERIOD BETWEEN 1783-1800 71 port in Europe, not being a -port of this kingdom, nor a port of that country to which such ships, being neutral ships, shall belong." There was the same pro- viso as in 1794 for seizure of cargo on neutral ships when it belonged to enemy subjects, " to whatever port the same may be bound." The special exception thus introduced was in favour of British ports, and was devised to carry out Pitt's policy of making England the store-house and toll-gate of the world's commerce. Its result was to make deviation at an American port unnecessary. The deviation to the Continent now occurred in England; the re-exportation which had been contrived at such a port as Marblehead could now be contrived at such a port as Plymouth. The Instructions with their concessions, the commer- cial policy which prompted them, the attempt of the American trader still to evade the restrictions and to gain further concessions, form a special theme which does not fall within the compass of this Memorandum, [t culminates in the doctrine of " continuous voyage," and, when that in its simple form proved too weak to check the ingenuity of the neutral merchant, in the evolution of the auxiliary doctrine of " common stock," which was made the test of a genuine importa- tion into the neutral country. The subject does, however, hold a definite place in the historical evolution of the spurious " Freedom of the Seas " ; and it is, perhaps, the best illustration of the motive of the neutral which underlies it, to secure the profit resulting from a successful voyage successful that is, in getting his goods to the enemy, in spite of the obstacles created by the belligerent ; and of the motive of the enemy in supporting the doctrine, to secure the successful landing of the cargoes. 1 1 The limitations attached by the late Professor Westlake (in his work International Law War, 2nd edn., p. 203) to the principle of continuous voyage may be referred to here in order to enter a caveat against doctrines which, if they were true, would make the principle worthless and reduce sea-power to impotence. VIII THE SECOND ARMED NEUTRALITY, 1800 THE foregoing survey of the events which happened between the outbreak of war in 1793 and the end of the eighteenth century will serve as an introduction to th.e consideration of the causes which led to the formation of the Second Armed Neutrality. It sprang directly out of the convoy question, its principal feature being the emphasis laid on the inviolability of the neutral Hag, behind which, as a screen, stood the old claim to freedom of trade with the enemy. Eng- land did not deny the sanctity of the neutral flag. But she did deny that, with the question of ships' timber and naval stores unsettled, the neutral flag could pro- tect these disputed cargoes on their way to the enemy. The " right of convoy " per se is not a very trouble- some question. It is based on the existence of a pro- hibition by a neutral Government to its merchants against shipping contraband, and requires the accept- ance of a statement by the commander of the escort, after due examination, that there is no contraband on the convoyed ships. With the question of contraband not merely unsettled, but very much in dispute, it was obviously impossible for England to acquiesce in the contention. But the Armed Neutrality principle was specially unpractical, because it contemplated mutual convoys; and therefore the statement of a Russian officer was to be accepted as to goods on board, say, a Swedish ship. The "right of convoy" was a direct counter to the "right of search"; as an auxiliary to the contraband dispute, it was no more than an ingenious method of getting round it. The neutrals displayed further ingenuity in putting forward their case. In the voluminous correspondence which followed each seizure of their ships the real question in dispute whether ships' timber was contra- ARMED NEUTRALITY, 1800 73 band was hardly, if at all, mentioned. To assert the inviolability of the neutral flag, and complain of the N ' insult" involved in visit and search, was therefore to assume a dispute to be settled which was not settled. The same flag hoisted on a warship did not improve the position. ' But the presence of the warships led to firing, and compelled England, in her turn, to complain of forcible resistance to the search. Thus there was also an "insult" to the English flag. It had been fired on when peace existed between the two countries. Each country, therefore, demanded apology and reparation from the other. It will be useful to quote a caustic remark upon the convoy question by M. de Martens, the impartial and dispassionate collector of diplomatic documents. Alluding to the decrees of the Directory issued in 1798, referred to in the last chapter, he says 1 : "However revolting these decrees, they were tolerated by the Northern Powers; at least no alliance was formed to resist them. But they sufficed for Denmark and Sweden to increase the number of these convoys, even in the seas in which they had not done so before, and where they had less to fear from France than England. Measures legitimate in themselves, but which had never been regarded with favour by belligerents." England contended that " the right to visit mer- chantmen at sea is an incontestable right of a nation at war. Resistance to a friendly warship must be con- strued as an act of hostility." The Danish contention (case of the Havfrueri) may be thus summarised : The right of visit is recognised by custom and treaties ; it is not a natural, but a purely conventional right; and it cannot be extended arbitrarily beyond what has been agreed or accorded. No Power has ever admitted the right to visit ships under escort; they could not do so " sans de"grader leurs pavilions, et sans renoncer a une partie essentielle de leurs propres droits." Far from acquiescing in this hitherto unknown pretension, the majority of the 1 De Martens, Recueil, Supplement II, p. 346. 74 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' neutral Powers have thought it right to enunciate the opposite principle in their conventions with the most respectable Courts in Europe. The distinction made between convoyed and non-convoyed ships is as just as it is natural. The right of visit in respect of non- convoyed ships is limited to verification of their flags and examination of their papers, in order to establish their neutrality, and the regularity of their bills of lading. If these are in order, further visit is illegal. Thus the authority of the Government which issues them ensures the requisite security for belligerents When that Government convoys its merchantmen, it offers to belligerents a more authentic guarantee than is afforded by the papers, and it cannot consistently with its honour admit of doubts and suspicions, in- jurious to itself and unjust on the part of those who raise them. To the suggestion that some small neutral State might cover illicit commerce by its flag, it was an- swered (case of the Freya): "a suspicion of such vile conduct is as injurious to the Government creating it as to the one which did not merit it. The officers have made themselves personally responsible that the convoy contains no contraband; and it is easy to see that it would be more difficult to escape the vigilance of such officers than of those who pretend to exercise the illusory and odious right of search." It is not necessary to refute this argument piece- meal. It was a fact that many neutrals had thus limited the right of search among themselves in their treaties by interposing the escort of a warship ; but it was equally true that these treaties had been entered into with the express object of supporting this con- tention after the affair of the Dutch convoy in the Downs in 1779. The facts remained that the merchant- men were full of ships' timber and naval stores for France, or it would not have been worth while risking a naval engagement; and that England did not and could not admit that they were non-contraband. 75 The British answer (case of the Havfrueri) may be condensed into one sentence: ' The honour of the King's flag has been insulted almost within sight of his coasts, and this action has been sustained by contesting indisputable rights, founded on the most evident rights of nations ; from which rights His Majesty will never depart, but the moderate exercise of which is indispensably necessary for the maintenance of the dearest interests of his Empire." , In August, 1800, Lord Whitworth, supported by a squadron under Admiral .Dixon, was sent to Copen- hagen to negotiate an amicable arrangement, Den- mark seems then to have recognised the essential differ- ence in the fundamental principles asserted by her and Great Britain, and proposed arbitration by Russia, "which is friendly to both States." The answer was that " there is no Sovereign in wtyom Great Britain has greater confidence than the Tsar. Nevertheless, it is hoped that Denmark will so act as not to render it necessary." The result of the negotiations was that a preliminary convention was signed at Copenhagen on August 29, by which the Freya was released, and Den- mark agreed to suspend her convoys until a definite convention was entered into. The alliance between England and Russia was still in : force; but the glamour of Bonaparte's genius and military successes had begun, to fascinate the Tsar Paul, and his friendship for England was gradually weakening. The appeal of the neutrals over the convoy question led him to follow his mother's example, and he issued a Declaration to the neutrals based ori Catherine's, inviting them to renew the Armed Neutrality. The Declaration opened with a flamboyant refer- ence to the Declaration of 1780, to which it was alleged , that Europe had given its approbation. It then referred to the case of the Freya. The Tsar believed that the King of England would disapprove this violation of the Law of Nations and of the principles of neutrality. Nevertheless, in order to 76 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' prevent the recurrence of such acts of violence, it was necessary to re-establish the basis of neutrality, ki so that the neutral nations may enjoy the fruits of their industry, and not be subject to arbitrary measures of belligerents, and therefore to re-establish the principles of the Armed Neutrality, and secure the ' Freedom of the Seas.' Kussia would employ all necessary force to maintain the honour of its flag." The dates of the several incidents .at this time are a little difficult to follow. With events passing in different parts of Europe allowance must be made for the time taken by the couriers. The Russian Declara- tion was issued on August 16, apparently immediately after the receipt of the Danish complaint about the Freya, without leaving time for the negotiations with England to mature. The English squadron passed the Sound on August 19 ; and, news of this having in due course reached Russia, Paul immediately ordered the sequestration of English capital in Russia. This was on the 29th, apparently on the same day as the pro- visional convention was signed between England and Denmark. On the arrival of this fresh news some days later, the sequestration was withdrawn. On December 4/16, 1800, a convention was signed between Russia and Sweden " to re-establish the Armed Neutrality, which had been adopted with so much success during the American war."- It referred to the indestructible principles of neutrality, and the neces- sity which existed to enforce respect to them, " de re- tablir dans son inviolabilite le droit commun a tous les peuples de naviguer et commercer librement et in- dependamment des interets momentanes des Parties belligerantes." The "maximes bienf aisantes " of 1780 were to be renewed; and the four principles then enunciated were in substance repeated with a fifth added the " right of. convoy." These principles have already been analysed. It is necessary, however, to re-emphasise what has already been said. All the principles in reality turned on the question of contraband. The League declared ARMED NEUTRALITY, 1800 77 they would recognise as contraband only those " re- putes munitions de guerre et navales." The con- tracting Powers would prevent most rigorously the commerce of their subjects in contraband as thus de- nned ; but ' ' ils entendent et veulent que tout autre trafic soit et reste parfaitement libre." On this basis, and on no other, rested the principle of " free ships free goods." Even if the premisses had been good, the conclusion was hopelessly false. There was no con- nection between the two propositions. The principles were to be applicable to all maritime wars in the future, and were to be regarded as a permanent guide to the contracting Powers in matters of commerce and navigation, " et toutes les fois qu'il s'agit d'appre"cier les droits des nations neutres." The provisions of this convention were renewed by Russia and Sweden in a treaty of friendship and commerce, March 13, 1801. A convention in identical terms was entered into on 4/16 December, 1800, between Russia and Denmark, and a similar one with minor alterations on 6/18 December between Russia and Prussia. The mutual accessions of each Power to the other treaties were completed in February 1801. One other incident in connection with this new Armed Neutrality must be recorded. Catherine's de- claration had been addressed to the belligerent Powers; Paul's was addressed to the neutrals. England heard of what was going on, and at once asked Denmark for explanations. The correspondence can best be fol- lowed by extracts, which show a curious sincerity on the part of Denmark, probably shared by Sweden, in the principles they advocated. It cannot, be said that the English despatches put the case very clearly. The point hinted at above, on which everything turned, vas not referred to granted that trade in all com- lodities other than contraband was free, granted even .m agreement as to what was contraband, how could these propositions establish the freedom of enemy goods on neutral ships ? The enemy goods might not 78 have been the subject of any commercial intercourse with any neutral merchant; the shipowner might be no 'more than a gratuitous carrier-bailee. No argu- ments were advanced to prove that one principle fol- lowed from the others. Nothing was said on bur side to show how remote they were. And yet there was a connection almost studiously kept in the background: the enemy property which the neutrals claimed to carry free was the ship's timber and naval stores they had sold to the enemy. By joining the League, Catherine had said in 1780, the Dutch Republic " secured its navigation and the trading industry of its subjects, which was for the most part carried on in favour of the enemies of England." The British note to Denmark of .December 27, 1800. requested a frank explanation why she was engaged in negotiations hostile to England. There was talk in all Courts of Europe of a confederation between Denmark and other Powers "to oppose by force the exercise of those principles of maritime law on which in great measure the naval power of Great Britain rests." She had waited for Denmark to deny these rumours; but the conduct and public declarations of one of these Powers made it impossible to wait longer. The Danish answer is dated December 31 : " London must have received very inexact information to suppose that Denmark has conceived hostile projects against 'England, and Denmark is much obliged for' the opportunity of denying the rumours in the most positive manner. Negotia- tions at' Petersburg have no other object than to renew the engagements which were contracted in 1780-1781 between these same Powers for the protection of their navigation. Den- ' mark did not hesitate to accept the proposal of Russia, be- cause, far from ever having abandoned these principles, she has supported and claimed them on all occasions^ and has never 'admitted any modifications other than those resulting from, treaties with belligerent Powers. Far from wishing to hinder these, Powers in the exercise of the rights w'hieh war gives, them, Denmark only brings to the negotiations views which are absolutely defensive, pacific, and incapable of offend- ing or provoking anyone." 79 It was then contended that the provisional arrange- ment which had been entered into at Copenhagen on August 29 (by which the Freya had been released) ' ' cannot be opposed to the general and permanent prin- ciples which the Powers of the North are on the point of establishing in concert, which far from compromising their neutrality is destined to strengthen it." Den- mark hoped that this explanation would " be quite satisfactory, and would cement the ancient friend- ship." This answer admitted that a treaty was on the point of being ratified which united Denmark to a Power with which England was no longer on terms of neutrality. Her retort was to impose a general embargo on Russian, Danish, and Swedish ships. The British note explaining the reasons for the em- bargo dealt with the change in the Russian attitude towards the principles of neutrality; especially em- phasising the fact that at the commencement of the present war "Petersburg, which took the leading part in the coalition [of the Northern Powers in 1780] formed an alliance with England, which not only was .not in accord with the convention of 1780, but was actually entirely opposed to it." Those engagements were still in force. ' The only conclusion possible from the coalition and from the activity of naval arma- ments, was that the Powers have no other object than to support by force pretensions which so evidently deny justice. The Power which first put them for- ward in favour of neutrality was also the first to abandon them when she went to war." To which Denmark answered, " The principles of the sacred right of neutrality have never been abandoned. When Russia was at war she simply deferred their applica- tion." It was, however, perfectly true to say that Denmark and Sweden had " announced in the face of Europe [that is to say, in 1794] the unchangeableness of the system they had adopted for the protection of all licit commerce." The Second Armed Neutrality, "a coalition more menacing in appearance than in reality ' came to 80 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS " aD end with the assassination of the Tsar Paul and the defeat of the Danish fleet at Copenhagen. On March 24, 1801 : Paul was succeeded by Alexander; and, as the material interests of Russia at that time pointed to peace with Great Britain, a treaty of the first import- ance was signed on June 5 of the same year, by which mutual concessions on questions of maritime law were made. In the words of Mahan, 1 it " permitted the neutral to trade from port to port on the coast of a nation at war, but renounced, on the part of Russia, the claim that the neutral flag covered enemy's goods. On the other hand, Great Britain admitted that property of a belli gerent, sold bona fide to a neutral, became neutral in character, and as such not liable to seizure; but from the operation of this admission she obtained by a subsequent arrangement the special exception of produce from the hostile colonies. This, Russia conceded, could not be carried directly from the colony to the mother-country, even though it had become neutral pro- perty by a real sale; and similarly the direct trade from the mother-country to the colony was renounced. Great Britain thus obtained an explicit acknowledgment of the Rule of 1756 from the most formidable of the maritime Powers, and strengthened her hands for the approaching dispute with the United States. In return, she abandoned the claim, far more injurious to Russia, to seize naval stores as contraband of war." 1 Mahan, op. cit., Vol. II, pp. 261, 262. IX NAPOLEON AND " LA LIBERTE DES MERS " WITH the overthrow of the Directory and the assumption of the government of France by Bonaparte as First Consul, the history of the spurious " Freedom of the Seas " enters a new phase. From a somewhat nebulous doctrine advocated by the neutrals it hence- forth takes definite shape and is asserted by the enemy. This formed part of Bonaparte's general policy of taking the neutrals under his wing and compelling them to do his bidding. " As against Great Britain's control of the sea no State had a right to be neutral " (Mahan, II, 247). He even went the length of imagin- ing that he, a belligerent, might be admitted to the League of the Neutrals. We have it in Bonaparte's own words that he sought admittance, but was refused : " La France, qui a deja propose* d'y entrer et avait ete refusee." This fact has led me to question the statement made in the Cambridge Modern History that " the voice was the voice of the Northern League, but the hands were the hands of Bonaparte." This opinion must, I think, have been based on the " friendship " which appears to have been gradually developing between the Emperor Paul and Bonaparte. But Paul was then almost the declared enemy of England. It is by no means clear that his relations with Sweden were very cordial. Even had he lived, the Second Armed Neutrality would have proved but a rickety machine at the best. But with his assassination it fell to pieces, and the way was clear for Bonaparte to take charge of the neutrals. His first step was to remind the new Tsar of the League and to invite him to [1947] G 82 "FREEDOM OF THE SEAS' continue its work, indicating that he could not refuse to do so consistently with honour. " Si la Eussie continuait son systeme cle neutralite armee, dont il ne parait pas qu'elle puisse -s'eloigner avec honneur, la France, qui a deja propose d'y entrer et avait ete refusee, etait encore dans les memes dispositions." In this attempt he was foiled; and the alliance be- tween Great Britain and Russia w r as restored by the treaty of 1801. From this moment we find in Bona- parte's letters and speeches his authoritative exposition of the " Freedom of the Seas " ; and its object is clearly denned. It was to get rid of the supremacy of England on the sea. It was the necessary prelude to assuming it himself, and thus to secure the domination of the world. The shaping of the scheme was begun in a letter to Talleyrand, February 1800. He is to collect as quickly as possible all the facts which would help to establish England's violations of international law. The iniquity of England in the exercise of her domina- tion of the sea was to be the text on which he proposed to preach to the neutrals, exhorting them to activity against his enemy. The instructions for drafting a note to the Tsar concerning the surrender of Malta contained the fol- lowing : " II serait-dit dans cette note que le Gouvernement franqais, ay ant principalement a coeur de s'opposer a I'envahissement des mers et de concourir avec les autres Puissances neutres a faire respecter leurs pavilions . . . ne traitera de la paix avec 1'Angleterre qu'autant que ces principes sacres seroient re- connus . . . et qu'il serait reconnu par 1'Angleterre que la mer appartient a toutes les nations." When, in answer to the Russian embargo on English ships, an embargo was imposed on Russian ships in English ports, Bonaparte issued a decree protecting Russian commerce. Talleyrand was to send it to Russia with this explanation : " Que la Russie ne se trouve dans cette disposition cbntre 1'Angleterre que pour la defense des droits de principaute* de toutes les nations, et que pour delivrer les mers de cette nation, qui, a elle seule, pretend en etre la dominatrice. . . . Je NAPOLEON BONAPARTE 83 desire que S.M.I, voie dans cet acte de propre mouvement la consideration et 1'estime que j'ai pour elle et pour la grandeur de son caractere." Napoleon's message to the Senate after the conclu- sion of the Treaty of Luneville in February 1801 is conceived in the same strain. Speaking of King George III he says: " Tout le commerce de 1'Asie et des colonies immenses ne sufiisent plus n son ambition ; il faut que toutes les mers soient soumises a la souverainet^ de 1'Angleterre. II arme contre la Bussie, le Danemarc, et la Suede, parce que la Russie, la Suede, et le Danemarc ont assure, par des traites de garanties, leur souverainete" et 1 'independence de leur pavilion. Les Puissances du Nord injustement attaqu^es ont le droit de compter sur la France. Le Gouvernement franqais vengera avec elles une injure commune a toutes les nations." But the projected alliance with Russia, always hoped for, never quite achieved, seemed the surest method of accomplishing his design. " La paix avec 1'Empereur," he writes to Joseph, his plenipotentiary at LuneVille, " n'est rien en comparaison d'une alliance qui maitri- sera 1'Angleterre et nous conservera 1'Egypte." From denouncing England for all her alleged iniquities on the sea he passed easily to the promise of better things in store for the neutrals, which would result from the restoration of the supremacy of France at sea, when the oppression of all seas and of all peoples would come to an end: " L' Europe opprime*e n'a plus qu'un de"sir raisonnable k former, et ne doit placer ses ressources que dans une seule espe"rance, le re"tablissement de la puis- sance maritime de la France." The possibility of establishing a naval supremacv and of making good the cry, " Brisons le sceptre de oette Rome de la mer!" had been almost annihilated by the battle of the Nile ; and the effect of that victory on the neutrals had to be dissipated. An article was published in the Mercure de France, and reprinted in the Moniteur, in which the power of the sea was decried and the power of the land extolled. The con- clusion was thus boldly stated :" Jamais done, la [1947] H 84 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' raison le dit, et 1'histoire 1'affirme, une puissance mari- time n'a triomphe d'une puissance continentale." He had forgotten Kichelieu's maxim, "La puissance en armes requiert non seulement que le roi soit fort sur la terre, mais aussi qu'il soit puissant sur la mer." It was the great dream of Napoleon's life, which, as Mahan points out, ultimately led to his ruin, to unite the Continent against the British Islands, and, as he phrased it, " to conquer the sea by the land." 1 Yet his attention never wandered from the sea question. Free cargoes on neutral ships were still as essential to him as they were to Louis XVI in 1778. Philosophers had devised another theory, which was more captivating than the rather vague principle of free ships making free goods, namely, that of the im- munity of private property at sea. The suggestion seems to have been first made by the Abbe* de Mably in a work on " Le Droit Public de 1' Europe fonde sur les Traites," published in Geneva in 1774, and appears to have come into vogue among the philosophers who abounded in France at the end of the eighteenth cen- tury. This was the weapon which Bonaparte needed, one which was easier to handle than the older maxim with its dubious premiss and its still more dubious con- clusion. It invited a larger appeal to the senses by clothing commerce with universal humanitarianism to the complete concealment of profit and loss. Thence- forward Bonaparte used it freely in his attack against England ; and it was reinforced by another theory, still more vague, and resting on an inaccuracy that war on the sea ought to be conducted, in the interest of humanity, according to the same principles as war on land. The second of these principles was merely an auxiliary to the first. The two must be read con- tinuously, thus : Private property should be immune from capture at sea because it is immune from capture on land, since war on the sea should be conducted on the same principles as war on the land. Any attempt to treat the two ideas as independent leads to con- 1 Mahan, op. cit., Vol. II, p. 271. NAPOLEON BONAPARTE 85 fusion, as the debates in Parliament in connection with the Declaration of Paris prove. The theory of the immunity of private property, and also the auxiliary theory, have been completely de- molished by Admiral Mahian in his War of 1812, published in 1906. He points out that private pro- perty is as immune at sea as it ought to be (but is not) on land, and that to take it is common theft, which war does not authorise ; but that, when the property of mer- chants is sent across the sea, whether it be ships or cargoes, it is merged in fhe larger term " commerce," which is national, because the national wealth depends on it. The theory is, therefore, no more than a device for achieving immunity of commerce, and strikes at the foundation of maritime warfare. Another important aspect of the question must be noticed. The arguments of the Manchester School, forcibly put by John Bright in the debate in -1862, sup- ported "free ships free goods" as a beneficent prin- ciple, but held that it was incomplete. If enemy goods were to be free, there was no reason why the freedom should be limited to those goods on neutral ships ; and, if the goods were free, the ships ought also to be free. By this process of reasoning Bright also came to support the "immunity of private property " theory. This argument emphasised the vice of the argu- ment of the supporters of the maxim after it bad been introduced into the Declaration of Paris, namely, that " free ships free goods " was a concession to the neutral alone, and did not confer any benefit on the enemy. Lord Palmerston declared that the Declaration of Paris related entirely to the relations between belligerents and neutrals, and that immunity of private property at sea related entirely to the relations of belligerents to each other; that the two doctrines were distinct, and rested on totally distinct grounds. What has already been said on the subject of the maxim is sufficient to show that the contention is unsound. Bonaparte definitely incor- porated these two theories into his policy against 86 ' FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' England, and formulated them in the preamble of the Berlin Decree, November 21, 1806, which was his answer to the blockade of the French northern coast established in May 1806 : " Les dispositions du present d^cret seront constamment con- siderees comme principe fondamental de 1 'Empire, jusqu'a ce que 1'Angleterre ait reconnu que le droit de la guerre est un et le meme sur terre que sur mer; qu'il ne peut s'etendre ni aux propri^tes privees, quelles qu'elles soient, ni a la personne des individus etrangers a la profession des armes ; et que le droit de blocus doit etre restreint aux places fortes reellement investies par des forces suffisarites. ' ' This decree was followed by the British Order in Council of January 1807, and this by the first Milan Decree of November 23, 1807. In the preamble of the second Milan Decree of December 17, 1807, the refusal of England to accept " free ships free goods " is re- ferred to, thus linking up all the different theories and doctrines into the main principle they had been devised to support: "Les Anglais .... ont profite de la tolerance des gouvernements [neutres] pour etablir Tin- fame principe que le pavilion ne couvre pas la mar- chandise." This decree was to remain in force until the British Government " sera revenu aux principes du droit des gens, qui sont aussi ceux de la justice et de 1'honneur." We thus return to the point from which we started, the doctrine which the Due de Bassano's report endeavoured to deduce from the Treaty of Utrecht. X ABANDONMENT OF THE ARMED NEUTRALITY PRINCIPLES IN his speech in the House of Lords in 1856 on Lord Colchester's motion expressing regret at the signature of the Declaration of Paris, Lord Derby, replying to Lord Clarendon's defence, said that " all the Powers who entered into this solemn League [the Armed Neu- trality of 1780] very soon abandoned their principles within eighteen years." The Importance of the fact is very great, but it requires some explanation. The main cause was, of course, the complete subver- sion of all preconceived ideas during the war with Revolutionary France. England was consistent in basing her action at sea on the historic right of seizing enemy property on neutral ships ; but her first 'and im- mediate ally was Catherine of Russia. In her indigna- tion at the murder of the Lord's Anointed by the " six hundred monsters " who had assumed to govern France, she threw all the principles of the Armed Neutrality to the winds, or, as Denmark interpreted it, " she simply deferred their application." On March 25, 1793, the two Powers entered into an alliance, en- gaging reciprocally to shut all their ports to French ships, and to take all other measures in their power for injuring the commerce of France; and " to unite all their efforts to prevent other Powers not implicated in the war from giving any protection whatever, directly or indirectly, in consequence of their neutrality, to the commerce or property of the French on the sea or in the ports of France." To grant the protection of the neutral fla^ to the property of a belligerent, in other words, to enable that 88 " FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' belligerent to claim the benefit of the principle " free ships free goods," would be within the exact meaning of the words " giving protection, indirectly in conse- quence of neutrality, to the property of the French on the sea." Russia, therefore, as a belligerent, engaged to invite the neutrals to abandon the principle which, when herself neutral, sh6 had exhorted them to main- tain. Those of the Powers signatory to the Armed Neutrality Convention of 1780 who accepted the invita- tion Prussia, Austria, the Two Sicilies, and Portugal did therefore expressly abandon the principle. The glamour with which the war had been invested by the Allies, who regarded it as an "occasion of common concern to every civilised State," did not alter the fact that it was a war in which this principle, if it were really founded on natural justice, as they had originally maintained, should have prevailed both for the benefit of the neutrals and of belligerent France. This was the attitude taken by Denmark in answer to the invitation: " Le droit des gens est inalterable, ses principes ne depen- dent pas des circonstances. . . .La nation [i.e., France] existe . . . les liens de commerce subsistent aussi. . . . La nation reconnait encore ses traites avec nous, elle s'y conforme, du moins frequemment ; elle les reclame et nous les reclamons, et cela souvent avec succes non-seulement pour nous, mais aussi pour les effets appartenant aux Puissances en guerre cou- verts par notre pavilion." The attitude of France is still more important, be- cause in her answer to Catherine's Declaration she had relied on the alteration of her maritime law in 1778, by which "free ships free goods " had been adopted. The various decrees affecting neutral ships with English goods on board were in direct violation of that principle. Holland very early in the war fell under the dominion of France, and the decrees were made applicable to the Batavian Republic. Spain, when she joined France, must also be taken to have abandoned the principles she professed in her answ r er to Catherine's Declaration in 1780. The ABANDONMENT 89 United States entered into a treaty with England in 1794, in which seizure of enemy goods on neutral ships was recognised. By the treaty entered into between Great Britain and Russia in June, 1801, the claim that the neutral flag covered enemy goods was renounced, and in 1802 Denmark and Sweden adhered to the treaty. 1 Assuming that there is anything in the suggestion that the upheaval caused by the French Revolution might justify the abandonment of any principle, a sug- gestion implied in the Danish despatch with reference to the case of the Havfruen that Russia had only deferred the application of the principles because she was at war there is a still more important case of abandonment, that of Sweden in 1789 during her war with Russia. She openly renounced the principles of the convention of 1780 ; and it is said by Manning that Russia tacitly followed her example. 2 This action of Sweden evoked Sir William Scott's caustic remark in his judgment in the Maria (1C. Rob. 340): " The law and practice of nations (I include particularly the practice of Sweden when it happens to be belligerent) 'gives 1 The abandonment by the adhering Powers of the principles of the Armed Neutrality is given somewhat differently in a note to Lord Grenville's speech in the House of Lords in 1801, in con- nection with the Treaty concluded with Kussia in that year. The several renunciations were : " By Kussia, in her war with Turkey, in 1787; by Sweden, in her war with Russia, in 1789; by Russia, Prussia, Austria, Spain, Portugal, and America, in their treaties with Great Britain during the present war; by Denmark and Sweden, in their instructions issued in 1793, and in their treaty with each other in 1794; and by Prussia again in her treaty with America, in 1799." (Letters of Historicus, p. 102.) This note appears to have been prepared for the published edition of Lord Grenville's speech. The last statements are not accurate. While Denmark, in the instructions issued in 1793, did recognise the right -to seize enemy goods on neutral ships, the Swedish instructions did not. The treaty between Sweden and Denmark in 1794, as well as that between Prussia and the United States in 1799, dealt with the question in the spirit of the Armed Neutrality. 2 International Law, p. 268. 90 ' FREEDOM OF THE SEAS ' them [i.e., certain speculations and ' loose doctrines of modern fancy '] no sort of countenance; and, until that law and prac- tice are new modelled in such a way as may surrender the known and ancient rights of some nations to the present con- venience of other nations (which nations may perhaps re- member to forget when they happen to be themselves belligerent),. no reverence is due to them." While it is untrue to say, as is so often said, that a principle recognised in many treaties becomes thereby a principle of the Law of Nations, the converse is true, that a principle, even though admitted in many treaties, must cease to have any claim to be a principle of that law when one of its supporters openly de- nounces it. Whatever merit it may possess as a prin- ciple which some nations choose to concede to their potential enemies, whatever may be the number of nations which accede to it in their treaties, all claim to be a natural principle of the Law of Nations, to be an equitable principle which neutrals have a right to insist on at the hands of belligerents, must disappear when it is found that even one of those who most warmly supported it when neutral deliberately abandoned it when it was itself engaged in war. THE LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Santa Barbara THIS BOOK IS DUE ON THE LAST DATE STAMPED BELOW. UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY A 001 075 373 9