UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT LOS ANGELES GIFT OF CARNEGIE ENDOWMENT Publications of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace Division of Economics and History John Bates Clark, Director JAPANESE MONOGRAPHS EDITED BY BARON Y. SAKATANI, D.CL. Formerly Minister of Finance of Japan Conscription System in Japan, by Gotaro Ogawa. Expenditures of the Russo-Japanese War, by Gotaro Ogawa. Military Industries of Japan, by Ushisaburo Kobayashi. War and Armament Loans of Japan, by Ushisaburo Kobayashi. War and Armament Taxes of Japan, by Ushisaburo Kobayashi. Expenditures of the Sino-Japanese War, by Giichi Ono. War and Armament Expenditures of Japan, by Giichi Ono. EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR BY GIICHI 0N0 Councilor of Finance Department NEW YORK OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS AMERICAN BRANCH: 35 W«si :i:'sn sireet LONDON, TORONTO, MI-LB. n KM- AM) BOMBAY 1922 COPYRIGHT 1922 BY THE CARNEGIE ENDOWMENT FOR INTERNATIONAL PEACE PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA AT THE RVMFORl) PRESS, CONCORD, N. H. NOTE BY THE DIRECTOR The plans of the Division of Economics and History of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace have been transformed by the World War. Problems now calling for study transcend in importance those with which this Division has been dealing and material for research and record so far transcends any that was formerly available that it will demand ^ almost exclusive attention for some years to come. A new *£ world has evolved suddenly out of the world which we knew and the transformation extends to the foundations of gov- ernment and of economic life. ing to labor an increase of control — a change that if con- tinued will entail momentous consequences; but still greater effects have been produced on the relations of states to each other. The world as a whole has changed more than its component parts and the new relation of the parts to one another is the critical element in the situation. The great increase in the economic functions of governments is one cause of this condition. Within the great international com- munity in which the several states are units extensive eco- nomic functions have gravitated into the hands of govern- ments and caused them to face each other as business rivals and to deal with each other in a multitude of ways in which the merely self-seeking policy of private business is intoler- al >Ie. Power to invoke principles of justice and international law as interpreted by a competent court has become an in- dispensable means of allaying strife and this fact exalts to supreme importance the high court of nations which has just been established. It magnifies also the importance of the nomic facts and principles with wmich the law itself will have to deal. It is not merely individual men or private corporations who now meet each other in the rough and tumble of a world-wide mart but states themselves, each representing its own population and seeking to foster its interests as a zealous and faithful agent. The chances of friction that are inherent in ordinary commerce inhere today in vast international transactions and will increase in the measure in which the intercourse grows. All this means a NOTE BY THE DIRECTOR vii great increase in incentives to warfare, on the one hand, and in the motives for preventing it, on the other. Private com- merce unites more than it separates those who participate in it, and it remains to be seen whether international commerce will act in the same way; but, in view of what modern war means, the human race will deserve to perish, and much of it will probably do so, if the forces of strife are allowed to get the upper hand. Whether they will or not — whether the recent economic changes will tend to reduce warfare or to increase it — depends on the ability of nations to create and maintain the instrumentalities that in the new state of the world are necessary. Certain it is that the feeling which prevails today, the world over, is not one of security. The dread of further war is greater than it was before 1914. In some areas war still prevails, in others peace is held by a precarious tenure and in all it can be firmly established only by conscious and intel- ligent action by the states themselves. Mere exhaustion holds war dogs temporarily in leash, but it will take more than that to tame them as they must be tamed if peace is to endure. We here confront a wide difference between the several states in comparative desire for peace and disposition to maintain it. One portentous fact is the grim determination of Russian communists to extend their system by crude force from state to state. Bolshevism is government 1 >y t he few and largely the bad masquerading as government for and by the people. In its mother country, Russia, the economic meas- ure by which it began its career was confiscation of private wealth — in itself an ultra-democratic measure. If this had brought in a true communism, it would have been a ruthless and unjust measure for creating a peace-loving state. A just and orderly democratizing of industry in tin- several states would give new strength to the forces of peace, and it would be highly improbable that any state so influenced would try to extend its system over foreign countries by military invasion. Democracy, socialism, communism and bolshe- vism all appear in the aftermath of the war. The first of viii NOTF. BY THE DIRECTOR them makes i<* future peace and so does even the conserva- tive element in the second, while all else in the series means certainty of en il strife and danger of international war. The fad thai during the war governments had to take on innumerable functions that were formerly in private hands has Lent an impetus to socialism and to the perverted growths that have accompanied it, and it has created a new inter- ii.iii.Mi.il system the meaning of which is profoundly signif- icant, though he who runs can not so easily read it. There .ne dangerous features in the system which the war evoked and, happily for mankind, there are available safeguards which were evoked with them and need to be retained if human effort can do it. I >v a c< >mpulsi< >n that there was no resisting, the war forced the nations of the Entente into economic cooperation with each other. Commissions centering finally in the Supreme Economic Council adjusted in a harmonious way questions that would otherwise have led to rivalry and conflicting action in purchasing war materials, securing ships, appor- tioning food, controlling railroads, financing the war and doing a multitude of other things Avith the one common pur- pose of victory. The special compulsion of the struggle is over, but it has left an aftermath of issues grave enough to make peace insecure unless something equivalent to the Supreme Economic Council survives in full efficiency. The agency that did so much to win the w r ar can do so much to prevent another one, but to that end it will have to be guided by economic principles and it is a saving fact that these still survive. The war has not abolished the law of demand and supply, though governments may forget it. In the coming era they must build better than they now know. Economic knowledge must either go in advance of action and prevent disaster or follow action and be learned from disaster. Be- yond computation is the importance of attaining the knowl- edge and using it when evil impends and prevention is possible. John Bates Clark, New York, Director. September 2?, IQ20. AUTHOR'S PREFACE When Japan emerged from the old regime and instituted the present system of government at the time of the restoration of the governmental power to the Emperor, she was beset with many troubles both from within and without and the future destiny of the Empire seemed hanging in the balance. Yet, within no more than half a century, extraordinary changes have taken place and Japan has today become one of the great Powers, having developed her present state of national power and prosperity in that short period. Such a record is hardly paralleled in any other country. Japan's history, therefore, during the fifty years of the Meiji Era, has, it is needless to say, a unique place in the history of the world, while the Sino- Japanese War, which is treated in this book, has likewise an especially important position in this period of Japan's history. There are two reasons for assigning to it such special impor- tance: one is the effect of that war upon Japan; the other is its special effect upon China and the various foreign countries which had interests in the Far East. I shall, for the sake of convenience, call the former the internal, and the latter external, effect. The Sino-Japanese War was the first international war in which Japan had engaged since the restoration of Meiji. At first the people generally did not believe in the possibility of final victory, but fortunately for them the laurels were awarded to Japan at last. The nation then, tor the first time, realized the latent power which she had been conserving since the restoration, and henceforth Japanism as opposed to the Europeanism of the ante-bellum period has been encouraged, and the nation has constantly planned for the r the economic effects, they too have been very great. They have completely changed the economic relations of the Far East. Consequently, a discussion of that war in its relation to Japan and especially to the economic conditions of the Far East will help greatly in making clear how the new situation in the Orient has been brought about. The value of such dis- cussion is immeasurable. While, to be sure, this book does not go so far as to treat of the external effects of the war, yet, even as a discussion of the internal effects alone, the work forms a valuable history of the economic development of Japan. From this point of view- it may be seen how important the Sino-Japanese War was in the economic development of Japan. The author of this work, Mr. Keiichi Asada, has long served in the Department of Finance, where he has been actively en- ged in work relating to money circulation and finance. The t luu res which are assumed as basis of the arguments in this book were obtained after careful investigation and are trustworthy in the highest degree. Today, any one who wants to make investigations of the same kind must depend upon the materials in the possession of the Department of PREFACE XI Finance. The author has made good use of these materials. And there is only one thing to regret. That is, that, on account of the limited scope of the present treatise, the author could not adduce additional figures in proof of his arguments. However, he has not failed to grasp the general principles underlying those figures, and to this fact the present editor, in his concluding remarks, desires cordially to attest. Giichi Ono. Tokyo, Japan, May, igi6. BIBLIOGRAPHY Asada Ki ii< in, Treatise on the Fluctuation in Prices of Commodi- ties in Japan sine- the Meiji Restoration, and the Cause thereof I Meijilshin igo ni okeru Wagakuni Bukka no Hendo oyobi Sono den in ron) 1912. Ci rrj N( v System Investigating Committee, Report and Supple- ments (Kahei seido Chosakai Hokoku oyobi do Furoku), 1895. Department of Finance: References for Monetary Circulation (Kinyu jiko Sankosho), 1899-1910. Reporl of Financial Readjustment after the Sino-Japanese War {Xijit shichi hachinen eki Sengo Zaiseishimatsu Hokoku), 1900. Comparative Table of Figures for Forty-one Years relating to Foreign Trade of Japan (Dainihon Gaikoku Boeki Shijii ichinen Taishohyo), 1909. Animal Reports on Foreign Trade of Japan (Dainihon Gaikoku Boeki Nenpo), 1 882-1910. Annual Reports of the Department of Finance (Okurasho Nenpo), 1875-1911. Annual Statistical Reports of the Bureau of Taxation (Shuzei- kyoku Tokei Nenpo), 1885-19 10. General Staff of Japan, History of the Sino-Japanese War (Nisshin Senshi), 1904- 1907. [NABA, Kin/ax, Complete History of the Ching Dynasty (Shin did Zenshi), 191 4. KOBAYASHI, Ushisaburo, Treatise of x^djustment of Finance (Zaisci Sciri Ron), 1912. Oriix i \l Kconomics Publishing Co., Finance and Economy after the Sino-Japanese War (Niju shichi hachinen Sengo no Zaisei oyobi Kcizni), 1 903. Sakatani, Y. (representing the authors), History of Finance of the Meiji Era (Meiji Zaiseishi), 1904. Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, Annual Statistical Reports of the Japanese Empire, Xos. 1-34 (Nikon teikoku Tokei Nenkan), 1882 1911. Taki/.wy \, NAOSHICHI, Treatise on History of Japanese Money Cir- culation [Nippon Kinyu Skiron), 1912. YOSHIDA, Togo, History of Ancient Japanese-Korean Relations (Nikkan Koshi dan), 191 1. xii EXPLANATORY TABLES Value of Japanese Currencies Japan adopted the gold standard system in 1871, but the inconvertible paper money became principal currency a few years later. In 1886 the paper money became convertible into silver and after that date the Japanese currency system was the silver standard de facto, until on October 1 , 1897, the gold standard system was legally adopted. The figures necessary to ascertain the value of Japanese currencies are given below: (1) 1 gold yen (according to Coinage Law of 187 1) contains 1.5 gramme pure gold. (2) 1 gold yen (according to Coinage Law of 1897) contains 0.75 gramme pure gold. (3) 1 silver yen contains 24.261 gramme pure silver. (4) The value of I silver yen in the English currency (according to the demand rate of exchange on London in the average of the year) is as follows: 1874. 1875- 1876. 1877. 1878. 1879. 1880. 1881. s. d. 4.02.0 1882 4.00.8 1883 3. II. 2 1884 3"-7 1885 3 °9-4 1886 3.08.0 1887 3.08.9 1888 3.08.4 1889 s. d. 3.08.8 1890 3 07.9 1891 3 07.9 1892 3 06.0 1893 3 03.2 1894 3 02.0 1895 3 01 .0 1896 3 01 .1 1897 d 04 s. 3 2.02. 2. 10. .06. .01 .01 .02.0 .00.4 (5) The value of 1 yen of paper money in the English currency (calculated on the basis of the above mentioned exchange rate and the quotations of the silver price in the Tokyo Exchange in the average of the year) is as follows: s. d. s. d. s. d. 1877- 1878. 1879- 3. 10. I 1880 3 05.6 1881 300.3 1882 s. 2.06 2 02 2 . 04 I883. I884. I885. S. 2. IO.7 3 04-3 3 03.7 (6) I ryo (unit of value of the old currency system) was declared in the Coinage Law of 1 87 1 to be equal to 1 yen. Chronological Table Meiji 1st 2d " 3d 4th 5th 6th 7th 8th 9th " 10th " nth " 12th " 13th " 14th 1868 A. D. M -iji 15th 1869 " ' 16th 1870 " ' 17th 1871 " ' 1 8th 1872 " 19th 1873 " ' 20th 1874 " 2ISt 1875 " ' 22d 1876 " 23d 1877 " ' 24th 1878 " ' 25th 1879 " ' 26th 1880 " ' 27th 1881 " ' 28th 1882 A [884 1885 [886 1887 1888 1889 1890 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1). xm \ \ EXPLANATORY TABLES CHRONOD »GICAL TABLE — (Continued) 19th [896 A. D. 30th " " 1 " j2d (899 " " 33d 1900 " " 34th [901 " " 35th 1902 " " 36th 1 1 11 . ; j7th [904 (8th [905 39th 11,1,1, 40th 1907 " Mciji 41st 1908 A. D 42d 1909 " 43d 1910 " " 44th 191 1 " " 45th \ Taisho 1st J 1912 " 2d 1913 " " 3d 1914 " 4th 1915 " " 5th 1916 " " 6th 1917 " Weights, Measures and Money With English, American, French and German Equivalents Great U. S. of Japan Britain America France Germany Rl = : f\! !"a„ I 2.44030 2.44029 3-92727 392727 = 2.100 A, » Miles Miles Kiloms. Kiloms. = 12,900 Shaku. ... 1, ... Marine / l ■ I 5 I 52 I-I5I5I I -85318 I.85318 Kl (Marine) j MUes Miles Kiloms. Kiloms. c rll . ir , ,,,- /5-95505 5-955oi- I5-42347 I5-42347 bc l liari lu \ Sq. Miles Sq. Miles Km. Carres Quadrat Km. Uw Z !!L 7 s' ." {2.45064 2.45062 99. 17355 99-17355 - IO "-' Acres Acres Ares Ar. = 3,000 Bu [ Tsubo= 10 Go / 3 .95369 3 95367 3 -30.S79 3-30579 = 100 Shaku.. . . \ Sq. Yards Sq. Yards Centiares. Quadratm. Koku= 10 To ( (4765389 1. 80391 1. 80391 = 100 Slid I 4.96005 J Gallons (Liq.) Hectolitres Hectolitres = 1 ,000 Go I Bushels | 5 . 1 1902 = 10,000 Shaku . . I [ Bushels (Dry) Koku (Capacity offi/ioof 1 10 of 1/10 1/10 ship) \ one Ton one Ton de Tonne Tonne ■ - 1 000 A Tnmmr [ 8 ■ 26 ~™ 8 - 2 6/33 3-75000 3 75000 11 32277 1.32277 0.60000 0.60000 2K»- 160 Momme. ...I J*; <£"*■> 1 T bs ;^. voir) Kilogs - Kil °^ ] I .60754 ! 60754 [ lbs. (Troy) lbs. (Troy) ""irsSft, i^.o.ssa 0.4984 2.583 2.0924 = I'^oilo 1 s - d - Do11 - Francs Mark. CONTENTS PART I — Expenditures of the Sino- Japanese War CHAPTER , PAGE I Introduction 3 II Disbursements of the War 35 III Supply of War Funds 47 PART II — Economic Effects of the Sino-Japanese War I Introduction 81 II Effects on Public Finance 87 III Effects on the Money Market 152 IV Effects on Industries 208 V Effects on Commerce 224 VI Effects on Transportation and Communication 254 VII Effects on Primitive Industry 273 VIII Social Effects 278 IX Conclusion 320 Index 325 PART I EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Note. — In the tables throughout this volume, fractions of yen greater than one half have been counted as a whole yen and the other fraction- have been disregarded. CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ( ALSES OF THI-2 WAR What the Balkan peninsula has so long been to Europe, the peninsula of Korea has for centuries been to the Far East — a "haunted palace" wherein lurked an unceasing source of danger to the peace of the Orient. With a vast empire more than four thousand years old as its immediate neighbor on the one side and the indomitable Empire of Japan on the other, it was not strange that the peninsula never gave birth to a strong or independent nation, for it is scarcely possible for small trees to flourish among giants of the forest. With an area of some 75,000 square miles (almost as large as Italy) and a population of about 12,000,000 (more than that of Scandinavia) the country can not be regarded as insignificantly small; yet, overshadowed as it was by two great masculine powers on either side, it never evinced re- markable virility or greatness. The comparative smallness of the peninsula, however, has been the main reason why the rulers of the land were unable to maintain undisturbed rela- tions with their neighbors or establish a stable government. Notwithstanding the fact that various monarchies arose in the peninsula from time to lime, each in turn assumed a char- acter either of half-hearted independence or of meek sub- ordination, ever at the mercy of its more powerful neighbors whom it sought to humor by continual evasion, obsequious- ness and adulation. No sacrifice of national honor or prestige was too great for the maintenance of a mere existence. Indeed it is scarcely too much to say that there m \ er has existed any really independent government in Korea, as tin- feeble and fickle national entities of the peninsula have always wavered in uncertain existence through the political upheavals and changes constantly taking place on the Asiatic continent. It was this continued political instability of Korea that ren- 3 4 EXPENDITURES OF Mil SINO-JAPANESE WAR dered the country a menace to the peace and welfare of Japan and the whole of the Far East. I vi ;i the Li dynasty, which five hundred years ago over- threw the kingdom of Korai, was unable to prove more per- manent than its predecessors, following along in the same path of inconstancy and fluctuation. As its power declined from year to year it resorted to every possible temporizing expe- dient that suggested itself for the prolongation of its life. Japan, while she showed sympathy and sought to help Korea become a vigorous and independent power, free from disin- tegrating disturbances, was helpless to effect reform, as she always found her good offices ignored or treated with discourtesy. In spite of the repeated misdeeds and incivility of Korean officialdom during the early part of the Meiji Era, Japan persisted in her policy of leniency and willingness to forgive, protecting the peninsula from aggression and leading all other nations in recognizing its independence by signing a treaty to that effect in 1877. But notwithstanding these efforts for peace and reform, the misguided officials of Korea gave this all-important question no consideration, but, on the contrary, devoted their time to internecine strife in following out their petty ambitions for higher authority, often engaging in peril- ( »us schemes for crushing their rivals. Thus, both the national and international affairs of the country were left to go their own way. All this time China had been regarding Korea as a depend- ency of her own, and was interfering both directly and indi- rectly in the internal affairs of the helpless country. It was but natural, perhaps, that China should mistrust and dislike Japan's paternal attitude toward Korea and try by every means to prevent greater intimacy between them, a .policy which finally culminated in the uprisings of 1882 and 1884. h o\ these insurrections was due to a struggle for superi- ority between the Conservatives and Progressives, the one party siding with China and the other with Japan, time driv- ing them farther and farther apart. Consequently after the INTRODUCTION 5 disturbances of 1884, in order to prevent an unwelcome con- flict with China, Japan concluded the Treaty of Tientsin, which recognized and authorized equality of rights for both Japan and China in the peninsula. Nevertheless, China obstinately continued to regard Korea exclusively as her own dependency, thus paying little or no attention to t he- treaty. Having long maintained a footing in Korea, China now assumed an aggressive and menacing attitude, contrh ing so to complicate the situation as to render it intolerable to Japan. Apparently it was China's policy to subject Japan to insufferable pressure and leave her to take what course she would, knowing that the island empire could not continue to go on yielding step by step to the aggressor. Thus was laid the egg from which was hatched the Sino-Japanese War. Historically, of course, there should have been no ground of conflict between Japan and China. Their relations from the earliest days had been those of friendly neighbors, has ing their common roots in similar doctrines as to government, nature of civilization, law, art, literature, religion and moral- ity. In former times Japan had in main- lines been a pupil of China, imbibing the virtues of early Chinese civilization which in ancient times was remarkably advanced. But with the incessant expansion of European activity in the Orient, Japan was well-nigh obliged to strike out for herself and soon left China far behind. Japan labored earnestly for the intro- duction of enlightened laws, form of government and mode of living; whereby she soon grew into a nation far superior to her former self and also to her big neighbor, from whom she had once been contenl to learn. Meanwhile, ( Ihina remained unchanged, confined to the rut which she had trodden for thousands of years. Already separated by a narrow sea, the two nations now became separated by differences in civiliza- tion and national policy, the one aspiring to enjoy the best of western civilization, the other slumbering in antiquated Asiatic conventionalism. Consequently, though Japan had once regarded China as a great nation, she now could not but consider her as stubbornly conservative, incapable, and even 6 EXPENDIT1 RES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR moribund; while China, on her side, looked upon Japan with contempt, as an upstart and a shallow imitator of western barbarians in fact, a mischievous and diminutive empire thai could accomplish nothing great. Thus estrangement grew ever more pronounced as the two countries fell further and furt Ikt apart in thought and action, until at last the inevitable open conflict was seen to be close at hand. Moreover, the natural pride and mutual suspicion of the two countries, of nearly equal strength, now tended to accen- tuate mutual hatred and jealousy and each began to take warning and prepare for a sudden rupture of relations. The Loochoo and Formosan questions, discussion of which we reserve for later treatment, would not have led to repeated failure of negotiations, and finally to trouble, had China and Japan been on friendly terms at the time. The unhappy estrangement was then far advanced and ever growing wider and deeper; and so, after the disturbances of 1882, Korea became the principal cause of dispute between Japan and China. The Togakuto affair only brought the trouble to a head, and showed that at some time in the future Japan would be forced to take up arms to settle her difficulties with China, to ensure reform in Korea, and peace in the Orient. As the fate of Japan was bound up with that of Korea she could no longer endure the ever-increasing maladministration and degradation of the hermit kingdom. In addition, China's constant disregard of her treaty with Japan, especially after the Togakuto difficulty, her treating Korea as still a Chinese dependency, together with her attempts to intimidate Japan to gratify her own caprices, rendered conflict inevitable. Though Japan was well aware of the backward state of China, she yet had no desire to come to blows with so great and ancient a nation. Nothing but absolute necessity for the defense of her own existence would ever have induced Japan to take ii]) arms against China. In short, the Sino-Japanese War was a conflict between two civilizations that had grown too dissimilar to exist longer in harmony side by side; but the Korean question was its INTRODUCTION 7 immediate cause; and it was specifically the means whereby Japan sought to establish permanently her own independence and the peace of the Far East. In Japan sympathy with Korea was universal, coupled with a strong desire to check the arrogance of China by a chivalric blow. Doubtless, as in all wars, there were other contributory causes, for never in the history of the world has any country gone to war and undergone sacrifice of men and money merely for the sake of another nation! Definite proof of this contention could be advanced in examples beyond number. Japan's ultimate action against China was not without good cause for it was for the sake of her own existence and for Oriental pe NOw, we shall proceed briefly to review the historical relations between Japan and China, the immediate cause of the war, the disbursements consequent upon the war, and the eco- nomic effects of the war. Historical Relations between Japan and China The war between Japan and China brought to an end the dispute as to Korea, driving the Chinese forces permanently out of the peninsula; and furthermore it introduced Japan to the outer world, assigning her a new position among the powers. The war, moreover, exposed the weakness of China and hastened the decline of her territorial integrity. Soon afterwards she was compelled to submit to the German occu- pation of Kiaochow, to lease Port Arthur to Russia, Weihai- wei to the British and Kwangchow Bay to the French, all sweeping changes which occurred immediately after the war. Before that time there had been some aggression on the part of Western Powers in China, such as the Opium War, the Franco-British allies' capture of the Taku forts, and the Sino-French War; but these were insignificant compared to the inroads which took place after this war. Thus Japan opened the eyes of European Powers to possibilities in the Far East at a time when there was nothing in Europe to tempt their lust for territorial expansion. Historically, as well as geographically, the Korean peninsula I \i'l \|.i i I R] S OF I HI SINO-J IPANESE WAR has been the bridge by which Japan lias always sought access to the continenl of Asia; and at the same time she lias always irded it as a barrier to assure her territorial safety. It is clear from the pages of history that, as the unification of the empire became more firmly established and population expanded, the overflow ever sought relief in the direction of Korea. Expeditions to Korea by the Emperor Sujin, the Empress Jingo, I lideyoshi Taiko, as well as the argument for Korean invasion in the early part of the Meiji Era, are vivid experiences in the memory of Japan. In his history of Korea, Dr. William Elliot Griffis well says that it is impossible to discuss the history of the peninsula without taking Japan into consideration, just as one can not deal with medieval English history without including France. Having had so intimate an historical relationship with that country, the Japanese mind feels naturally both familiar with and friendly toward the Korea of today. From the dawn of Japanese history comes the tradition that Susano-no-Mikoto dispatched his son Isotake-no-Mikoto to Korea to occupy and rule Soshi- mori in the kingdom of Shiragi; and mythology suggests that Okuninushi-no-Mikoto transported from Korea the ter- ritory with which to extend the promontory of Kizuki in the Izumo Province. As there is usually some substratum of fact underlying tradition, we may infer that intercourse between Japan and Korea has been intimate and unbroken from earliest times. It would, therefore, seem but natural that Japan should occupy a part of Korea in establishing her relations with the continent of Asia. As to China's relations with Korea, it must be remembered that that dynasty, as soon as it attained full power, invaded and oppressed t he peninsula without mercy. Modern intimate relation- between the two began about the year 1620, in the reign of the Emperor Tai Tsung of the Chin dynasty, after which time the Chinese practically exercised suzerainty over Korea and extorted tribute from her; yet, shrewdly enough, whenever any trouble arose over affairs in the peninsula, China tried to escape all responsibility, even to the extent of INTRODUCTION 9 denying her protectorate, while Korea in each case handed all the profits to her overlord. Although China thus for- mally denied her authority over the country, she never \"V a moment abandoned it in fact; and, consequently, when the trouble arose with Japan, the Chinese Government, having already lost her reputation for diplomacy, had no recourse but an appeal to arms. The first trouble with foreigners came in 1865 when a French missionary was assassinated. Prince Heung-Sun, father of the then Emperor of Korea, better known as Tai-Wonkun, cast over the government the shadow of his blind nationalism; and when a Russian ship visited Wonsan, requesting permis- sion to trade with Korea, the Prince asked the French mis- sionary Bellenue to request the foreign vessel to leave the port at once. The missionary declined to interfere and the Prince, suspecting him of being a European spy, had him beheaded. When satisfaction was demanded by the French Legation at Peking the Chinese authorities endeavored to evade responsi- bility by replying that the peninsula was no longer a poss sion of China. In the following year, when the wreck of the General Sherman and the massacre of her crew on the banks of the Taidong River created international complications, China again tried to shift the responsibility, answering that she had no authority over Korea in matters relating to war and peace. Yet tw<> years afterwards, when Japan sent an embassy to Korea for the purpose of acquainting the penin- sular government with the Meiji Restoration and consequent political changes and al><> to renew friendly relations, the Koreans (being stirred up by China), suspected Japan's motives, and treated the embassy with disdain. In [872 Japan brought to an end the practice of sending a tribute- bearing vessel from the Tsushima elan and proclaimed free commercial intercourse, stationing an official at Fusan for this purpose. Bui Prince Heung-Sun offered an unwarranted official insult which created universal indignation in Japan, where there arose a general demand for the chastisemenl «>t Korea. In the following year Count Soejima was dispatched [0 EXPENDITURES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR to < liin.i to requesl explanation of the offense and to ascertain definitely the exact relation between ( 'hina and Korea; where- upon the Chinese Governmenl denied, as before, that it was in any way responsible for Korea, saying that the peninsula was in no sense a vassal state. Although the Japanese Government and people endured with remarkable patience the insults inflicted by Korea, the latter country in no way amended her attitude; and in August, i s 7 5 , when Lieutenant Commander Ryoka Inouye, who had been engaged in surveying operations on board the warship Unyo, anchored off the island of Kanghwa near Seoul, he was fired upon by the island forts. The Japanese ship replied and destroyed the forts as well as killing 35 of the garrison. Upon the affair being reported by the Commander to the Japanese Government, Japan immediately dispatched her men-of-war to Fusan, to protect the Japanese there. In 1876, an envoy was at once sent to demand satisfaction, the mission including Kiyotaka Kuroda as chief and Kaoru Inouye as vice minister. This embassy requested satisfac- tory settlement of the Kanghwa question and the opening of K( >rean ports to trade. Aritomo Yamagata, then Minister of War, proceeded to Shimonoseki with troops so as to be ready for any emergency. The repeated negotiations proved abor- tive and the embassy was about to abandon its fruitless efforts and return when suddenly Bokukeiju, a state councillor, and ( roko, an interpreter, revolted against Prince Heung-Sun and insisted on opening the peninsula to trade, to which the Korean Government finally assented; and on February 26, 1876, a letter of apology was offered for the Kanghwa Island affair and a treaty of 12 articles signed, the main points of which were that (1) Korea was to remain an independent kingdom and enjoy relations with Japan on equal terms; that both countries should be ready to exchange envoys at any time necessary; (3) that after 29 months Korea was to open two ports to trade, Japan having leave to station con- suls there; (4) that Japanese navigators were to have permis- sion to survey Korean waters; and (5) that cases of trouble INTRODUCTION I I among the nationals of either country residing in the two open ports were to be settled by the officials of the nationals concerned. The treaty being duly signed the Japanese representatives returned, and the Korean Government dispatched a special envoy to Tokyo to strengthen the friendship with Japan, while the latter created a legation in Seoul, sending Yoshikata Hanabusa as Charge d'Affaires. In 1887 when the Korean authorities attempted to expel all foreign missionaries, tin- French Minister in Tokyo endeavored to have the Japanese representative in Seoul mediate for the relief of the mission- aries, and the Japanese Government opened negotiations in the matter; but, discovering in the Korean reply phrases that indicated Korean acknowledgment to being a tributary state of China, Japan objected, and Korea reported the matter to China. As the Chinese reply contained similar contentions, Japan rejected that also. No further discussion was carried on, as Japan's treaty with Korea had already settled the matter of that country's independence. Previous to this, in 1872, there had been trouble in Formosa, when some natives of Miyako Island, Loochoo, who had been ashore in Formosa, were murdered by the natives, tin- same crime being repeated in the following year on men from the prefecture of Oda. To avoid a repetition of such out- rages, the Tokyo Government made Loochoo distinctly a Japanese possession, instead of allowing its ruler to pay tribute both to Japan and China as before, and dispatched Count Soejima to China to carry on negotiations. Up to this time about half of Formosa had been under Chinese rule, while the rest was abandoned to anarchy. China, as usual, endeav ored to fight shy of responsibility, denying that she had any auth< >r- ity over the island. But alarmed by the overwhelming vic- tory of the Japanese expedition to Formosa, involving, as it did, the surrender of numerous clan chiefs, China demanded the withdrawal of the Japanese force-. Japan refused to comply with the demand but after various n« gotiations agreed to evacuate on condition that China recognize Japan'- - 12 l XPENDIT1 RES OB THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR ereignty over the Loochoo Islands and pay an indemnity of 500,000 taels. In consequence of the increa Ing influence of Japan in Korea and the intimacy thai now marked their relations alter the settlement of the Kanghwa affair, as well as on account of Japan's firm attitude in regard to the Loochoo and Formosan questions, China began to feel uneasy and wished to check the further advance westward of Japan's influence. To achieve this object with some appearance of tact, China invited Occidental Towers into the peninsula, the United States being the first to be so favored. She even dispatched a warship of her own to bring over the American envoy, and it is said that Li Hung Chang himself drew up the articles signed by the United States and Korea. He, moreover, informed Prince Heung-Sun that to form a treaty with West- ern Towers was the best way to ensure the safety of Korea. Great Britain, Germany and other powers at once followed the American example. Here we see clearly the change of Chinese policy toward Korea. But notwithstanding all the efforts of Li Hung Chang to carry out his plans secretly, there was a sudden turn of affairs, which had its origin in the politi- cal disorder that occurred in Seoul in 1882. In accordance with the treaty of 1876, Korea opened the port of Wonsan to trade in May, 1880, and proposed to open Chemulpo, to which Japan had sent a surveyor, in July, 1882. By this time Japanese influence was becoming dominant in the Progressive party in Korea and a strong organization was effected. In addition, important reforms were brought about in the military system of Korea, and Lieutenant Hori of the Imperial Japanese Army became instructor. The leaders of the Progressives were Kim Ok Kiun, Hung Tiyong Ou and Li Sai Ben, who had the sympathy and support of the leader of the Mins. The Conservatives were led by Prince Heung- Sun, who hat i'd everything foreign and began an intrigue inst the Japanese and the Progressive party. The Mins, who wire members of the family of the Queen of Korea, had for main' years tilled the highest offices of state. The Con- INTRODUCTION 1 3 servatives now planned to drive out the Japanese, even if it required force. The native soldiery were deprived of proper rations until infuriated, and then were told all sorts of mali- cious stories about the Japanese. On pretext of punishing Min Ken Kwong, a member of the Min clan, for some slight offense against army regulations, a furious mob gathered and began to hunt the Japanese to death, and the legation was attacked. The Japanese' Minister, Hanabusa, with over twenty of his fellow countrymen, fought his way out into the terrorized streets of Seoul and escaped to Chemulpo, where he embarked on a junk and was picked up by a British ship and taken to Nagasaki. This outbreak took place on July 23, 1882. Upon receiving the report of the Japanese Minister regard- ing the affair, the government sent him back to Seoul on August 20, to demand an explanation of the King. In the meantime, Prince Heung-Sun had already assumed the reins of government and on the minister's arrival showed no sign of a conciliatory mood. The latter was, therefore, obliged to withdraw to Chemulpo. Then Li Hung Chang, fearing that Japan might either kidnap Prince Heung-Sun or dethrone the King in some plot with the Prince, dispatched a body 1 >f t n « »] is under Yuan Shi Kai, Bakeuchu and Teijosho to Korea, the intention being professedly peaceful. Under pretext of inviting Prince Heung-Sun to a friendly conference, the Chinese laid hands on him and spirited him away to China. On the Prince's departure, the scene changed in a flash. The Progressive party assumed office and a treaty was signed at Chemulpo on Augusl 30, [882. By this agreemenl the Korean < Government had to apologize to Japan, and to permit the presence of Japanese troops in Seoul to protect the li ii<>n ; the cost of furnishing as well as of repairing the barracks for the guard had to be borne by the Government of Korea. Japan agreed to withdraw the guard after one year from the signing of the agreement if she deemed it safe to do so. Other clauses of the treaty provided for the opening to trade of Wonsan, Fusan, and Chemulpo, etc., and the port of Yokai- chin after a year, while the Japanese Minister and staff wire I I EXPENDITURES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR given permission to travel in the interior. It is significant thai a1 this time Japan again acknowledged the independen< e oi Korea, and consented to use in the treaty the date of the Korean i alendar, which was the lour hundred and ninety-first year from the founding of the dynasty. It was from that date also that the Korean national flag began to be used. The action of the Chinese in abducting a Korean prince and detaining him at Tientsin could only be regarded as one more proof of China's desire to treat Korea as a subject state. From this lime China endeavored by all means to associate herself with the home affairs of Korea, which finally com- pelled Japan to attempt to remove Chinese influence entirely from the peninsula. In January, 1883, the Japanese Government sent Shinichiro Takezoe as resident minister to Korea, allowing him a legation guard in accordance with the rights conceded in the treaty of Chemulpo. At that time Yuan Shi Kai was also in Seoul, barked by a considerable force, and was laboring assiduously, through the efforts of Min, for the establishment of Chinese influence throughout the peninsula, Min on his part aiming at promoting his own personal interests with the assistance of China. The Progressive party, being thus left in the lurch by Min, looked to the Japanese Minister for sympathy and waited for a favorable opportunity to strike an effective blow at the Conservatives, who were then wavering considerably, 1 ro ing to China's trouble with France over the Annam bound- ary question. On December 4, 1884, during an official dinner in Seoul to celebrate the opening of the Postoffice, the oppor- tunity was seized by Kin Gyoku Kin, Bokueiko, and others of the Progressive party to attack Prince Min, who, together with several of the ministers of the Conservative party, was assassinated; they further endeavored to place the King's palace under guard. The King having requested protection, a Japanese force under Minister Takezoe entered the palace and ensured safety. The next day a cabinet representing the Progressive party was formed, but at dawn on the succeeding day Yuan Shi INTRODUCTION 15 Kai, assisted by the remnant of Min's followers, attacked the palace. The Japanese force- defended it, but in vain. They finally had to retire to the legation, the King taking refuge with the Chinese forces and a Conservative cabinet being installed. That night the Japanese Legation was assaulted and the minister, accompanied by his staff, together with Kim and Hung, fled for their lives to Chemulpo, leaving the legation in flames. The Japanese Government then dis- patched Kaoru Inouye, Minister of Foreign Affairs, as pleni- potentiary to Seoul for the settlement of the trouble. Tin- Treaty of Seoul was signed on January 9, 1885, requiring an apology from Korea and the reconstruction of the legation and barracks at Korea's expense. Thus the affair was settled as far as Korea was concerned. But China had still to be heard from; and for this purp< Prince Itom, then Marquis, was di>patched to Peking, where he and Li Hung Chang drew up and signed the Treaty of Tientsin, on April 18, 1885. The treaty made no reference to the assault of the Chinese soldiery on the Japanese Legation at Seoul, but acknowledged the equal rights of both nations to send troops to Korea in case it should be necessary in the future. The clauses of tin- treaty provided (1) that China should withdraw all her troops from Korea, and Japan her legation guards, the withdrawal to take place within four months from tin- signing of the agreement, under pain of con- flict. The Chinese troops wen- to withdraw by way of M,h- ampo and the Japanese by way of Chemulpo. 2) Both countries agreed further to advise the King of Korea to train a modern army for the protection of the peninsula and the maintenance of order therein, and to have him employ foreign instructors for tin- purpose, neither country to send officers to fill the positions. (3) In tin- third place, it was agreed in the treaty that if in the future either Japan or China, or both, should have occasion to dispatch troops to EC >rea, they should open communication with each other as to the matter, and that when the cause requiring the entry of troops no longer existed, they were to be at once withdrawn from the country. [6 EXPENDITURES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR li was further stipulated thai if any of the troops in Seoul should be guilty of improper conduct China should punish them on the production of indisputable evidence. A general retrospect of the disturbance of 1884 shows that the Progressives were defeated on account of their too impetu- ous grasp of political power without sufficient forethought, and that the Japanese Minister was also somewhat rash in acceding too hastily to the King's request for protection, since the monarch did not sincerely trust him, but on the con- trary sought refuge under the flag of China. Moreover, the minister took no immediate steps for the correction of the Chinese soldiers when they assaulted the legation and slew some of its guards. It was but natural, therefore, that Japan's influence should gradually decline, while China's continued to grow more and more throughout the peninsula. The Conservative party soon became dominant, under the Chinese Minister, Yuan Shi Kai. He brought his influence constantly to bear on Korean diplomatic policy and the Korean Government in turn was ever inclined to heed his counsel. The whole situation became unfavorable for Japan, and the general attitude of the people grew insolent and offen- sive toward all Japanese residents, especially toward those engaged in commerce and industry. The most severe blow of the time to the Japanese was the issue of the Bokokurei of 1889. In September the authorities of Kankyodo suddenly prohibited the resale and export of agricultural products without any previous notice to the Japanese consul, in spite of the clause in the treaty requiring such notice a month, in advance. Although the same treaty clearly stated the necessity of drought or riotous disorder as the cause of such law, there was nothing of the kind. The loss inflicted upon the Japanese was quite heavy. Japan demanded the repeal of the measure and some indemnity, but her demand was left unheeded until January, 1893. Kin ( .\.>kii Kin, the leader of the pro-Japanese faction, was assas- sinated about thai time, during a quarrel between the sailors of a Chinese warship and some citizens of Nagasaki, and the INTR0D1 I 1 EON 17 Japanese Government had to make humiliating concessions despite the fact that the fault was on the Chinese side. In this manner conditions began to obtain derogatory to Japan's interests. The Korean Government brutally mutilated in public the body of Kin and exhibited it with immense gusto all over the country as an example of what should be the just fate of all traitors. The victim was called "the most vicious traitor Kin." Just about this time (April, 1894) the revolutionary move- ment of Tong Haks began to spread fiercely over the penin- sula, more especially in the provinces of Cholla and Chung- Chong. Although the Tong Hak belief was quite a foolish and superstitious one, supporters of the doctrine were found in every province of the country. As the population had long been suffering from the misrule of Min and were anx- iously awaiting a change, they at once favored the Tong Hak movement. The first definite outbreak occurred at Ko-Po in the province of Cholla, where maladministration had been particularly oppressive; and three provinces south of the Kanko River unfurled the flag of insurrection. The Tong Hak leader of this rebellious force in the south was Zempojun, who repeatedly expelled the governmental force. Terrified beyond measure by the situation, the Korean Government sought the intervention of China through the mediation of Yuan Shi Kai. As Japan was in the throes of political tur- moil in the Imperial 1 >iet at the time, China assumed that it would not be easy for Japan to take much interest in foreign complications. Under pretexl of guarding a tributary nation in her habitual manner, China sent troops into Korea, and tli is action she made known on June 7 to the Tokyo Govern- ment through her minister there. Japan at once denounced China's pretension- to suzerainty in Korea, and. in ai o irdance with the treaty of Tientsin, informed China of her intention to dispati t of China to regard Korea as a dependency of her own, and both openl) and secretly to interfere in her affairs. At the time of the recent civil disturbance in Korea, < hina dispatched troops thither, alleging the purpose to be tliat of affording succor to a suzerain state Japan, by virtue of the treaty concluded with Korea in 1882, and looking to possible emergencies, caused a military force to be senl to that country. Desiring to procure for Korea freedom from the calamity of perpetual disorders, and thereby to maintain the peace of tlic Far I 'ast in general, Japan in\ ited the cooperation of China to that end. But China, advancing various pretexts, declined the proposal. Thereupon Japan ,\>\\ ised Korea to reform her administration so that she might be able to preserve order and tranquillity within her borders, and to discharge the duties and respon- sibilities of an independenl state abroad. Korea had already consented to under- take the task. Bui China secretly and insidiously endeavored to circumvent and thwart Japan's purpose. Furthermore she procrastinated and tried to make warlike preparations by land and sea. Completing these preparations, she dis- patched large reinforcements to Korea with a view to the forcible attainment of her anil lit ions designs, and even carried her arbitrary attitude and insolence to the extent of opening fire on Our ships in Korean waters. Plainly China's object has been to render it uncertain where the responsibility for the preservation of peace and order in Korea lies, and not only to weaken the position of that state in the family of nations (a position obtained for Korea through the efforts of Japan) but also to obscure the significance of the treaties recognizing and confirming that position. Such conduct on the part of China is not only a direct injury to the rights and interests of the Empire, but a menace to the permanent peace of East Asia. From the action of China it can only be concluded that from the beginning thai country has been bent on sacrificing peace to the attainment of her sinister object. Under these circumstances, ardent as is our wish to promote the prestige of the country abroad by strictly peaceful means and methods, we find it impossi- ble to avoid a formal declaration of war against China. It is Our earnest wish that by the loyalty and valour of Our faithful subjects peace may soon be perma- nentb restored and that the glory of the empire may be augmented and ever stainless. Progress of the Sino-Japanese War The historical facts with regard to the question of Korean independence and the reformation of the government in that country, so necessary to an understanding of the cause of the war which began on July 25, 1S94, have now been given in outline. The struggle continued for eight months, during which time Japan won a number of decisive victories one after another and was soon ready to march upon the capital of China. Whereupon the latter consented to peace by ceding territory and paying an indemnity, while Korea was made INTRODUCTION 2 1 independent of foreign interference, peace being restored on April 17, 1895. It will now be in order to give a brief review of the progri of the war with China and to indicate the causes of the diplo- matic troubles which arose after the war. From the outbreak of the war to the battles of Ping-yang and the Yellow Sea The battle of Phung Island on July 25, 1894, was prepara- tory to the great campaign at Ping-yang and the decisive battle of the Yellow Sea. The three Japanese war-hip-, the Yoshino, a cruiser of 4,267 tons, the Akitsushinia, a cruiser of 3,150 tons, the Naniwa, a cruiser of 3,709 tons, forming the First Flying Squadron under Rear Admiral Tsuboi, had been guarding the west coast of Korea against Chinese transports carrying troops to Korea. On July 2^, when a Japanese flying column consisting of the above ships appeared off Phung Island, southwest of Chemulpo, the Chinese warships Tsi-yuen, a cruiser of 2,355 tons anc ^ tnc Kwang-yi, a gunboat which came from Chemulpo, came into view. As a state oi belligerency had not yet arisen the Japanese commander naturally expected to meet the Chinese ships with the ordinary formality, but to his great surprise the Tsi-yuen at once and without warning opened fire on the Yoshino at 7.52 a. m.. at a range of about 3,000 meters. Consequently the admiral of the Japanese fleet could do nothing but give orders to return the tire. No sooner had the two assailants been put out of action — the Tsi-yuen routed and the Kwang-yi driven ashore — than two other Chinese ships, the Tsao-kiang and the Kow- shing, a British boat, appeared, the latter transporting Chinese troops bound forAsan. While the Akitsushima was capturing the Tsao-kiang, the Naniwa ordered the Kow-sking to stop, at 9.15 a. m.. but the land force (.n the vessel compelled the captain to continue the course back to Tako. The older to stop and follow the Japanese vessel was repeated ses era! time-, but, as the Kow-shing took n<> notice of it. the Naniwa pursued and sank her at 1 p.m. The captain and others were rescued. EXPENDITURES OB ill!. SINO-JAPANESE WAR Another battle al Songhwan was fought on July 29. In accordance with the requesl of the King of Korea on the 25th, the Japanese Minister Otori, at Seoul, at once sent for a force from the brigade headquarters at Manriso to expel the Chinese troops at Asan. The force proceeded to Soshajo, s< ime ma enteen miles north of Asan and only about two miles north of Songhwan, where the enemy had established them- selves in a powerful stronghold. Songhwan is an important town on the Asan road. The Japanese brigade captured the place in short order while the troops at Asan fled without offering resistance. The Japanese force participating in this action consisted of four infantry battalions, one company each of cavalry, artillery and engineers, 3,000 infantry, 47 cavalrymen and 8 guns. The Chinese had 8 guns, 3,400 nun and a number of noncombatants. The enemy's killed and wounded numbered 500, the result of 63 shells, 191 rounds of shrapnel and 67,801 rounds of cartridges fired by Japanese, while the latter lost 33 killed and 49 wounded. It was after these two battles, one on land and the other on sea, that the Imperial Proclamation of War was issued, namely on August 1, and the Imperial Army headquarters were on September 13 moved to Hiroshima. The fact has already been mentioned that prior to the outbreak of war the Imperial Government endeavored to settle the dispute by peaceable means, dispatching a mixed brigade from the Fifth Division to Korea; but, seeing the hopelessness of such an attempt, the government abandoned the idea with the report of the battle of Phung Island on July 25. According to reports reaching the Imperial Government the number of Chinese troops in Korea, mostly around Ping-yang, was more than 10,000 (including those that had fled from Asan), and the Mixed Brigade at Seoul was rumored to be in danger. For this reason the remainder of the Fifth Army Division, namely, the divisional headquarters and the Tenth Brigade, was ordered to Korea, on July 21, and on August 14 half of the Third Army Division, namely, the Fifth Bri- gade, was moved. Landing at Fusan and Wonsan they at INTRODUCTION 23 once marched on Seoul. Lieutenant-General Michitsura Nodzu, Commander-in-Chief of the Fifth Army Division, left Ujina on August 4, reaching Fusan on the 6th and Seoul on the 1 8th. The Japanese forces already in Korea— namely, the Third and Fifth Army Divisions — were formed into the First Army under General Yamagata, on September 1, with orders to drive the enemy out of Korea; but until the arrival of General Yamagata the command was taken by Lieutenant- General Nodzu, the Fifth Divisional Commander. As to the Japanese forces already in the peninsula, the Oshima Mixed Brigade was at Ryuzan and Rintsushin, the Twelfth Regiment of the Tenth Brigade arrived at Wonsan on August 8, and the Fifth Brigade was expected there on the 26th — the former called the Sakryong detachment and the latter the Wonsan detachment. Half of the Tenth Brigade was scheduled to be at Chemulpo on the 23d. Consider- ing the dispositions of the troops at his disposal, Lieutenant- General Nodzu set September 15 as the day for the general attack on Ping-yang. The Oshima Mixed Brigade was or- dered to lead the attack, while the Sakryong and the Won- san detachments were to descend from the north and the Main I )i\ ision from the southwest, the total attacking force numbering 12,000 men and 44 mountain guns. The Chinese force numbered 15.000 men with 29 mountain guns, 4 field guns and 6 machine guns, protected by 27 forts, 15 on the south, 5 outside of Taidong gate, 4 on the north hill without the wall and 3 on Mount Peony. The enemy put up an exceedingly stiff defense, aided by the natural fast- ness « »f the castled forts. Against these fortresses and defense works the Japai troops fought arduously, and finally succeeded in routing the enemy, the Sakryong and Wonsan detachments occupying Mount Peony after making desperate attempts to storm it. The stronghold fell on the 16th, the Japanese having lost 180 killed and 500 wounded, and having fired 680 common shells, 2,128 shrapnel and 284,869 rounds of ammunition. The Chinese losses were 2,000 men, including General Tso-Paok- 2 | EXPENDITURES < >!■ THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR wai. w hile <><><> were taken prisoners. Thus in two (lays Japan completely demolished China's foothold in Korea. On sea the anus of Japan were also decisively victorious. On September 12 the Japanese squadron got wind of the present e of the Chinese squadron which was guarding trans- ports near the Taidong and the Yalu Rivers, and on the 14th the Main Squadron consisting of the Matsushima, the Chiyoda, the Fuso, the Itsuku-shima, the Hiyei and the Ilashidate, with the first Flying Squadron comprising the Yoshino, the Taka- chiho, the Naniwa and the Akitsushima, the third Flying Squadron comprising the Tsukushi, the Akagi, the Maya and the Chokai, together with a torpedo flotilla including the Kotaka, No. 22, No. 12 and the torpedo-depot-ship Yamas- hiro, accompanied by the Kaimon, the Iwaki, the Amagi and the auxiliary cruiser Saikyo, all proceeded toward Taidong and arrived at the mouth of river on the 15th. But finding no hostile ship there, the fleet left the Tsukushi, the Maya and the Chokai as well as the torpedo flotilla, the Iwaki and the Amagi at the river's mouth and set out northward. The contending fleets met on the 17th off Tamushan, when a brisk act ion of several hours ensued, lasting until dark. The Chinese fleet consisted of the Ting-yuen and the Chen-yuen in the cen- ter, followed by the King-yuen, the Sai-yuen, the Ping-yucn, the Chih-yuen, the Lai-yuen, the Yang-wei, the Tsi-yuen, the Chao-yung, the Kwang-chia, the Kwang-ping and three torpedo boats, the total displacement being 34,420 tons with a speed of from 11 to 18 knots. The Chinese had quick-firing guns, 70 below 30 c. m. and 9 below 12 c. m., as well as about 129 machine guns, and 31 torpedo tubes and two torpedo boats. The Japanese squadron, with the exception of the Saikyo, consisted of 11 ships representing 36,771 tons, with a speed of from [3 to 22 knots, equipped with 246 guns, 44 below 33 c. m., [90 quick-firers below 15 c. m., 29 machine guns and 37 torpedo tubes. Thus the Japanese fleet was superior in tonnage, -peed and number of guns. Fighting with brilliant dash and courage the Japanese succeeded in sending the Chao-yung, the Chih-yuen and the King-yuen to the bottom, INTRODUCTION ^0 while the Yang-wei was set on fire and the Kwang-chia blown up, the rest of the enemy's fleet suffering great damage. The Japanese lost not a single ship and had only 279 casualtii The Chinese Peiyang Squadron was not completely de- stroyed in this battle, but it was practically disabled and deprived of fighting strength, without further power over Korean or home waters. Japan, on the contrary, obtained complete freedom of the seas, for transporting troops and provisions to China without much fear of molestation. By these two actions on land and sea China entirely lost her hold on Korea, while Japan saw before her a clear path by way of the province of Shingking to the capital of China. The progn iss of the war having thus early taken such a favorable turn, the spirits of the Japanese were correspondingly animated. Parallel advance of the first and second armies and the sieges of Haicheng and Port Arthur The first army in Korea was now instructed by the Impe- rial headquarters to expel all Chinese forces from Korea, and to obtain full control of Kiuliencheng, Fenghuangcheng, Haicheng and Liaoyang, and to form another army to take possession of Port Arthur and Weihaiwei so as to prepare for a decisive campaign in the territory of Liaotung with the coming of the spring of the next year. In preparation for this invasion of Chinese territory General Yamagata had been ap- pointed commander-in-chief of the Firsl Army Corps, so called to distinguish it from the other at Pyenyang. General < K ama was appointed commander-in-chief of the Second A run ( )orps on the day the welcome tidings of victory reached Imperial head- quarters, and the two army corps were organized as follow s: First Army Corps Commander-in-chief: General Count Yamagata Third Provincial I division Fifth Brigade Sixth and Eighteenth Regiments Sixth Brigade Seventh and Nineteenth Regiments 26 EXPENDIT1 RES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Fifth Pro incial I >i\ Lsion Ninth Brigade Eleventh and Twenty-First Regiments Tenth Brigade Twelfth and Twenty-Second Regiments Second Army ( )orps Commander-in-chief: General Count Oyama First Provincial I )ivision First Brigade Firsl and Fifteenth Regiments Second Brigade Second and Third Regiments Sixth Provincial Division Twelfth Mixed Brigade Fourteenth and Twenty- Fourth Infantry Regi- ments Second Provincial Division (did not take part in battle of Kinchow) Third Brigade Fourth and Sixteenth Regiments Fourth Brigade Fifth and Seventeenth Regiments Special Besieging Corps (temporarily dismounted artil- lery regiment) h provincial division included two infantry brigades, one battalion each of cavalry, engineers, ammunitionists and transport men, one regiment of field artillery, with field tele- graph corps, stretcher-bearers, medical corps and communi- cation equipment. The Tenth Brigade of the First Army attacked and reduced Wiju on the left bank of the Yalu River, completing their task by October 17, while the Hooshan fortress fell on the 25th and on the 26th the Chinese abandoned Antung and Kiuliencheng without combat, thus placing all Chinese de- fenses along the Korean boundary in the hands of Japan. Although the Chinese had at Kiuliencheng no less than 19,750 INTRODUCTION 2J troops, with 8 1 guns, to Japan's 13,000 infantry, 350 cavalry and 78 guns, they were nevertheless so dispirited by the defeat at Hooshan that they fled from the castle without offering resistance. The Japanese casualties at Hooshan were 149; they fired 493 shells and 99,950 rounds of ammunition, and captured 78 guns with 4,400 rifles. After the fall of Kiuliencheng on October 26 the Japanese forces divided into two, the Fifth Division marching on Feng- huangcheng and the Third Division on Takushan, across the Tatungkow. The enemy set fire to and evacuated Feng- huangcheng on the 29th; the Third Division captured Tatung- kow on the 27th and Takushan on November 5, and on the 8th it came into direct communication with the Second Army Corps. Advancing from Takushan, the Third Army Divisi. m overwhelmed Yungancheng on November 18, fought an important battle near Taohotsuon December 11 and cap- tured Chaimucheng on the following day. The same force reduced Haicheng on the 13th and thus opened the road between Kaiping and Liaoyang. As the fall of Haicheng was so vital to the Chinese, they made repeated counter attacks for the recovery of the fort, a fierce battle ensuing on Decem- ber 19 at Konwasai near this castle. The Japanese force engaged numbered 3,960 with 30 guns, Vihile the Chinese numbered 9,200, with 6 field batteries protected by natural strongholds. The battle lasted five hours, reddening the fallen snow. After five bayonet charges the Japanese troops forced the enemy to surrender, but only when on our side 69 had fallen and 339 been wounded. The number of shells tired was 1,383 and rounds of ammunition (.5,241. The suc- cessive and decisive victories of the First Army Corps gave greater freedom for activity and achievement to the Second Army Corps. To the Second Army Corps had been entrusted the reduc- tion of Port Arthur, assisted by the First Army and the fleet. Between October 24 and 26 the First Division succeeded in safely landing at Huayuankow. Though Tatungkow and Takushan had not fallen at that time their fate was too well 28 I XPENDIT1 RES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR a in. . I For much attention to be given them. Consequently, the Firsl Army was allowed to proceed with its mission alone, and the Firsl Army Division faced the stronghold of Port Arthur. On the 6th the force captured Kinchow-ching on the way, driving the enemy into the road to Port Arthur. Most of tlif batteries near Talien Bay were silenced on the 7th by this First Division while the First and Second Armies came into direct communication on the following day and reached the point of attacking Port Arthur. With the fall of the 1 latteries around Talien Bay, the commander-in-chief of the Second Army moved its disembarking headquarters from Huayuankow to Talien Bay. The Mixed Twelfth Brigade, landing at 1 [uayuankow on November 7, was now brought to the army, in preparation for a general assault upon Port Arthur. On the 13th the number of the hostile garrison was estimated at about 12,000, besides some at Poolanteen, at the rear of the main fort ; but it was thought that the First Divi- sion and the- Mixed Brigade with the Special Besieging Corps would be sufficient for the reduction, without seeking the aid of the Second Division. The date of the attack was fixed for November 21. Port Arthur was guarded on its eastern shore by Huang- chinshan and attendant forts, with Mantonshan, 11 1 meters high, and several other forts on the western shore, while Sungshushan, 103 meters high, and Erhlungshan, 82 meters, with Chihuanshan, 126 meters, and Itzushan, protected the land approaches. Thus by these forts, a strong wall and [2,000 troops the fortress was well protected. Indeed the place seemed almost impregnable. The First Division of the attacking force was ordered to assail torts Sungshushan and Itzushan, while the Mixed Twelfth Brigade was given the task of reducing Erhlungshan and Chihuanshan. After some sanguinary onsets Fort Itzu- shan was captured at 7 a. m. on the 21st, then Sungshushan and again Erhlungshan by 1 [.30 a. m. The defenses from the rear having been thus reduced the First Division had no dif- ficulty in taking Port Arthur in the afternoon. The shore IN 1 RODIN i [ON 29 fortresses of Huangchinshan and Mantoshan held out a little longer, but by the late afternoon and following morning they too had been silenced, and on the 226 the flag of the Rising Sun floated over the battlements of Port Arthur. The forees which accomplished this great achievement con- sisted of 15 infantry battalion- representing 59 companies, 3 squadrons of cavalry, 4 companies of sappers, 6 batteries of artillery with 30 guns and 8 batteries of field artillery with 48 guns; it was found that the Chinese participat- ing were 9,500 on the land side with 18 pieces of heavy artillery, 48 lighter guns and 19 machine guns, while on the water front 3,200 men were engaged with the assistance of 58 heavy ordnance, 8 lighter guns and 5 machine guns, most of the force finally escaping to Kinchow. The Japanese forces suffered 288 casualties, firing 247 shells, 1,526 shrapnel and 179,562 rounds of ammunition. Capture oj Weihaiwei, in vicinity of Yingkotu and the Pescadores During the siege of Port Arthur the enemy made repeated attacks upon Kinchow-ching, which was a Japanese suppi irting point and guarded by only 3 infantry battalions and a section of cavalry. The attacks upon the supply depot on the fol- lowing day by the enemy that had tied from Port Arthur were also successfully repelled and proved no obstacle to the main siege. On the same day this repulse was made, China intimated through the American Minister her desire for the cessation of war. A part of the Firsl Division of the Second Anns- Corps captured Poolanteen and Foochou on December 6, while the First Brigade oi the Firsl Division took Kaiping on January 10, previous to which the Third Division of the Firsl Army had taken Haicheng, on December [3. Thus during the firsl half of January, [895, the Third Division of the hirst Army Corps maintained full control of Haiching; and the Firsl Brigade ol the Second Army Corps at Kaiping swept the whole southeast area. As the Chinese forces were driven 30 EXPENDIT1 RES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Lack toward the line of Yingkow, Niuchwang and Tien- chwangtai w it li Liaoyang at the right flank, they concentrated i heir nun along this line and on Haicheng and made three furious attempts to regain it on January 17 and 22 and Feb- ruary 16. A point had now been reached where the two fortes were face to face for the decisive issue. The Imperial headquarters had organized a flying column consisting of the Eleventh Brigade, being the Thirteenth and Twenty-third Regiments, taken from the Second and Sixth I Y< >\ incial 1 )i\ ision of the Second Army Corps, which together with an artillery battery was dispatched on and after January 10, for the purpose of landing at Yungching on January 20 and attacking Weihaiwei, where the remnant of the Peiyang Squadron had been taking refuge. Landing at Yungching on the 20th, the forces at once faced about for Motienling and Huanglinchi, the former an elevation east- ward of the entrance to the bay of Weihaiwei, facing the islands of Liukung and Jih. The force had four 24 c. m. guns, besides 64 heavy guns under 24 c. m., which it placed on the surrounding heights of Motienling; it received vigorous assist- ance from the Chinese fleet in the bay. The Japanese attack lasted but four hours, however, when the fortress yielded, the only remaining positions being the forts on the islands and in Weihaiwei itself. Our forces swept all the fortresses around the city of Weihaiwei on February 2, and by the 12th, as the result of the joint action of the army and navy, every Chinese ship in Weihaiwei had surrendered, and the Japanese forces were complete masters of Weihaiwei. The Chinese forces participating in this part of the cam- paign numbered 12,000 troops, and 15 warships of the Peiyang Squadron aggregating 30,250 tons. The warships were transferred to Japanese command and the captured crews were delivered under pledge as noncombatants. Having accomplished its task so successfully most of the Japanese force in Shangtung returned to the peninsula of Kinchow by March 1. During the middle of February the Third Division of the INTRODUCTION' 3 1 First Army which had been left on guard at Haicheng, and the Fifth Division of the First Army, which had been left at Kiuliencheng, braved the freezing temperature and marched north, capturing Anshantan on March 2 and Niuchwang on the 4th. The First Division of the Second Army at Kinchow also invaded Yingkow and took it on the 6th, and then these detachments of the two army corps reunited and approached Tienchwangtai. The Japanese forces taking part in the siege of Tiench- wangtai consisted of the First.Third and Fifth Army Divi- sions, involving 21 infantry battalions, 6 companies of cav- alry, 14 batteries of field artillery and 5 companies of engineers with 54 field guns, 30 mountain batteries and 7 mortars. The total force numbered more than 19,000. This was the largest force participating in any single battle of the campaign on the Japanese side. The attack opened on March 9 simul- taneously from three directions, the Third Division occupying the center, with the Fifth on the right and the First on the left. The enemy numbered more than 20,000, with 40 gun-. and they put up an exceedingly stubborn defense. But it was impossible to resist the terrific onset of the Japanese forces from three sides, and the fort was taken on the very day of the attack. After this defeat the Chinese lost all hope of regaining Port Arthur, a hope which they had ardently cherished since their first attack on Haicheng. The com- bined operations of the First (Third and Fifth Divisions) and Second (First Division) Army Corps were then completed for the present and they began to plan a campaign in the direc- tion of Chihli. The Imperial headquarters in the meantime had already planned for the occupation of the Pescadores, even before the capture of Weihaiwei. For this purpose an expedition southward was planned, and as soon as the enemy's fleel was no more and Japan was master of the ( lull" of Pechili, a mixed column of 3 battalions and a mountain battery left Sasebo on March 15, convoyed by the Southern Squadron, which had been commissioned for the purpose, consisting of the Mat- j2 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR .sushi mil, the Hashidate, the Itsukushima, the Chiyoda, the Yoshino, the Naniwa, the Takachiho, the Akitsushima and the Zstt&i. The islands were- duly occupied. Preparations for attack on Peking It will be seen that Japan became master of the Gulf of Pechili on September 17, 1894, as the result of the Yellow Sea fight, and Port Arthur on November 22, and was in pos- session of the whole territory east of the Liao River by March 9, 1895. The Peiyang Squadron was vanquished on Feb- ruary 12, 1895, and Weihaiwei taken; and as the Pescadores yielded on March 26, nothing remained to prevent Japan from transporting her forces across the Gulf of Pechili. In the early days of March the Imperial headquarters pro- jected a campaign into the province of Chihli by reorganiz- ing the various army corps already mentioned. The Second Army Corps was to include the Imperial Guards, the Second, the Fourth and Sixth Divisions, and it was to concentrate its main efforts on the taking of Shanhaikwan. The First Army Corps, including the First, Third and the Seventh Extraordi- nary Divisions, was commanded to march into and occupy the plains of Chihli. Thus the entire force consisted of seven divisions with about one-third of the whole second reserve. Although this force had to meet a Chinese army of more than 200,000 it nevertheless felt superior, as it doubtless was, in ( omparison of numbers. 11. I. H. General Prince Komatsu, Chief of the General Staff, was appointed commander-in-chief of the reorganized army, and was to have left Ujina, a port near Hiroshima, on April [3, establishing his headquarters at Shanghaiwan when taken, and from there to promote the attack on Peking. All such plans were then suddenly arrested by the arrival of pro- posals of peace. Reconciliation The first suggestion of such a proposal came on November 22, the date of the attack on Port Arthur, but it ended fruit- INTRODUCTION 33 lessly. China sent a representative to open negotiations on January 31, 1895, but there being some defei t in his commis- sion, leaving him without full powers, no conference could be held and he returned to Peking. On March 14 Li Hung Chang came to Shimonoscki as the fully accredited repre- sentative, and negotiations were opened on the 20th ; a treaty of peace was signed on the 17th of April, the exchange of ratifi- cations taking place on May 8. By this treaty ( nina agreed to recognize the independence of Korea, to cede Formosa, the Pescadores and the Liaotung peninsula to Japan, to open the ports of Shashih, Chungking, Soochow and Hangchow to Japanese commerce and to pay to Japan an indemnity of 200,000,000 taels. Thus Japan's aim in opening the war was attained and peace was restored in the Orient. After Japan's occupation of the Formosan Island the natives became more restive than before. Consequently the govern- ment dispatched the Imperial Guards and the Fourth Divi- sion, which carried out expeditions in various parts of the island for the subjugation of the savages and of the rebellious elements. This operation, however, need not be further dwelt upon, since it formed no real part of the Sino-Japanese War. Unreasonable interference by Russia, Germany and France: political turmoil in the Far East But scarcely had peace been restored when Japan had to face and submit to partiality and injustice, 011 April 23, on tin- pari of Russia, Germany and France, in being obliged to abandon the Liaotung peninsula, on the pretexl that her occupation of continental territory would be prejudicial to the peace of the Orient. Japan had purchased it with the tears and the blood of her son-, but she was compelled to relinquish it for nothing. So potenl a three-fold interferes e she was not prepared to resist. By this action Japan was humbled to the dust, a fact which it is well to note carefully. The three powers contended that the peninsula under the Japanese Hag would prove a constanl source of trouble in 34 EXPENDIT1 RES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Eas1 Asia. Japan yielded and abandoned the Liaotung pen- insula on May [0 and the three powers had their way. But did matters remain as they had contended they would? They ousted Japan and walked into her possessions themselves. ( Germany leased by force the Bay of Kiaochow on March 6, [898, Russia leased Port Arthur and Talien on March 27 of the same year, and on June 1 Britain got Weihaiwei. France could not be left out, and she got a treaty signed to lease Kwangchow Bay on November 16 of the following year. Thus the four powers, under pretext of leasing bases, started the disintegration of China. It was indeed a shrewd and ingenious means of snatching the prize which Japan had pur- chased with her blood and was soon after forced to forswear. In name it was an act of leasing; in reality it was an act of occupation. We have no desire to misrepresent or to confuse issues, but to state the simple truth as to the action of the powers. It is the practical rather than the theoretical side of the matter that Japan has to consider. She must be gov- erned by facts, not by names. It was indeed something Japan found, and still finds, impossible to understand: that these powers should have compelled her to relinquish her new- possession and then have proceeded to occupy it themselves. CHAPTER II DISBURSEMENTS OF THE WAR General Survey of Expenses The Sino-Japanese War opened on July 25, 1894, when Japanese warships were fired upon in the Hoto offing; and peace was restored by the Treaty of Shimonoseki, signed on April 17 of the next year. The space of war time extended about nine months (including the Formosan expedition) . The number of officers and men participating on the Japanese side was more than 240,000, together with some 6,495 civil officials and officers and some 100,000 laborers. The number of war- ships engaged was 28, representing a displacement of over 57,600 tons, with 24 torpedo boats aggregating 1,475 tons. The theater of operations extended about 268 miles east and west, and some 1,269 miles north and south, covering about 14,280 square miles of battleground in Manchuria, 18,445 square miles in Korea, 892^ square miles in Shantung and 5,652! square miles in Formosa, or about 39,270 square miles in all. As it was an oversea war, the cost was comparatively large. The total outlay has been put down at 235,866.0.^ yen, the period of disbursement running from 1894 to 1903, as tabulated on the following page. The actual total outlay for the war came to 233,523,252 yen, including the sum of 135-553 yen spent after [903, which will be accounted for later on. The total may be tabulated under (1) War Office, 194,777,467 yen and (2) Naval Office, 38,745,785 yen. Moreover, administrative expenses arising out of the war increased the outlay l>y 2,47s, ^54 yen, bringing the total up to 236,001,606 yen, which will be analyzed according to dis- bursements in due course. 35 36 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR .y o S.2 o £ U 3 O > u £ o rtfcS II hoO O00 C N VO - •t"'. cOO^-t- "-. I - ir, «- CO - 1 v£> co CO X IC -t -i ^5 N M O \oo nm h o n r^ cs O own c?oo c?. rf \o oT O cO O m N O rj- 1/} t>.\0 O M ■<*■ O "0 >-i 0) lO ON rj- tv. C?> r-; C> \r> in io rf co iooo >h hn w M io t^co i^ t>. •* qv o_ n m i-i o~ io CO tJ- Tf O vO iO CO « i-i CO co t^vO k.^ m" fi rf t? of Hi co co \0 t>. !-■ HI O HI -■ oo lO CO s«t Hi tJ-On NOO ON n" CO CO ON M s rj- co ^ -- M co oc CO CO CO CO co o* o o* 0\ u -2 .55 ■0° - — P-s 2| i- C Ci O |s of o o ■*->-cj ^s o o o u ■"- •■ x £ DISBURSEMENTS OF THE WAR 37 Cost of the War The total amount of actual expense for the Sino-Japanese War has been set down above at the figure of 233,523,256 yen, which, as has already been stated, represents the outlay by army and navy from June 1, 1894, which was before the war broke out, to March 31, 1896, together with certain further disbursements after the war for readjustment of affairs en- tailed by the war, compilation of war history and sundries. The outlay in detail of the War and Navy Departments may be seen from the following tables: Expenditures of War Office, 1894-1903" Fiscal years Extraordinary military affairs After-war adjustments Compilation of war history Grant of lump sum Total 1894 \ .... 1895/ •••• 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Yen 164,520,371 20,415,279 5.915.563 3,025,960 22,136 4.795 67 Yen 56,548 35.766 19,560 9,836 Yen 50,540 50,695 42,593 31,810 43,845 Yen 1-^5,197 82.4M, 123,689 37,108 28,070 1 'r /: 164,520,37] 2O.4i5.279 5,915.563 3,025,960 254.421 173.742 78,754 71,915 Total . . . 193.904,171 121,710 219.483 396,550 194,641,914 a Between the years 1904 and 1913 additional expenses in relation to the war were incurred as follows: 1 Compilation of War History and Statistics Grant of lump sum 74. 1 -'4 Total U5.55I When this outlay is added to tin- total outlined above, the grand total for the Wai 1 >ffice will be 194.777,468 yen. J^ /'{MS ; V S EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Expenditures of Naval Office, i 894-1902 Fiscal years Extraordinary war funds Compilation of war history Lump sum grant Total 1895 1 1896 Yen 35.955.137 [,449.76o 608,260 3H.744 122,585 253.513 1,602 Yen 3.094 Yen 34.327 i,43i 205 1,101 30 Yen 35,955,137 1,449,760 1897 608,260 1898 349WI 1899 124,016 1900 256,812 [QO] 2,703 1 902 30 Total 38,705,601 3,094 37,094 38,745,789 Analyzing the accounts of the War Office and the Naval Office, the items include arms, ammunition, supplies for troops and transportation of troops and provisions, as follows: Details of Expenditures of War and Naval Offices Items War Office Naval Office Total Yen 32,603,214 91,979,606 4i,37i,365 27,949,985 873,297 Yen 31,850,170 3,980,079 1,308,760 1,566,588 40,188 Yen 64,453,384 Supplies for troops Transportation of troops and pro- 95,959,685 42,680,125 Accessories to cost of war 29,516,573 9!3,485 Total 194,777,467 38,745,785 233,523,252 The above items, omitting those already explained, are fur- ther analyzed in the tables on pages 39-42. DISBURSEMENTS OF THE WAR 39 (^ U H u rt o 95 V on fa '"" rt H O y rt O fa *" u-. if. R} »- ON O o ta on I« OOO £» ; 1 . . NO £*M O M fO >t PI O NO X00 NO p*5 N Pt Pt n£> • ON "rt «- 00 ON 01 On t^ "* f^ 8 -' -Poo" M m -t ■4 c m 1- 1 -1- vo" »1 OOO ^>0 aNx't'N vO On •- ""> \r> fa > " H 1- 00 IO 1^ -1- "" 00 O IOVO * u-5 1- pOnO 00 -*• t~- C On - -t- • -J- On ci - 1 ~ <•< 00 C O Pt NO • ON rt i- t^ NO -+• Pt -t - 1-1 - PI 11 NO O fa M M M f 00 Pt PO O fa "■- C On lO On ON f ) u- ) 1T;C NN O PI O 1^- •+ I^nO a , N- O O -I" ' ON 00 00 O 00 C NO pi P.IOO • (4 uvo pi 9 t. C -1- . IO « CIJO .^ On rOOC lOOO f ^- C NN -1 tO« -1 NNlT,f<5 M ON Pt u. "•- - r-^ 10 po ON §S ~ PI PI M oc M c '/. - _ c — — Cfl •• is IT. ja§ £ c X^ c B rt L S"«3 - /. g en - — 7 c " •2 «o.C \ '1 y. - 00 > td 5 -r — a utensi ruction ase of 5 jlies ilari rovii othi oun rave ! r- is an rms orse amp onst urch fa 1. r* CLi ■1" EXPENDIT1 RES 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR H u ~ '■Z '-~ cd u o u cd c >. ~ a u o> CJ cd On Cd I- CO u rt o> w 01 oo t-r. >> >■* CJ Cd On M - X CO ■ M m" ; oo" 00 ON c O O t>- - CnnO O CO o o t-» Tf CM o « r>- n cm NO IO00 CO OMO RJ «- VO cj cd On rO O IO00 00 o ^ vO « r-~ i- ir> t^OO NO On CM_ ON rOCO NO* 00 iO r-» cm O H « ON ON lO t^ r>. o tC On Cm" mnDOO CM On .- > c M J3 c - c In X TJ-00 O ON CO M CO CO m >o to ON f^oo CO "+ 00 C 00 Tt- m lO CM CM cooo" On o" NO >ono o On O CO CM 0")hN O ^On t-~ oo tn o" 6 no" m" i-* CM CM NO Tf CM a o> 73 .S c 'u cd cd CJC-^H .9 Jj 3.2 "S 2 "Sol' O C3 <« -; rj C.JJ C 2 rt " 2 rt 5 8 C O i- o w u-- - cd •— • ^ o o> o c i- - .5 o 2 <« >n >N l.Egg •2JS UjC C <" *2 J" 0*t- cd *— * i- O Ui o.= c ~ o ^ '6' s » u o U £.5 C O C +3 «* cd ■_ bo o ■ . , C cd O > cd en U o cd «j ■/. en en O • to qj ~ c " c. 22 c c-o o - ~5 ="2 o in it i) n3 > j. 3 3 '-> > b en O O O OJ CJ O C C >,— — o"p"nV >>« ■— - cd (j 5 c 3 5 3 2. i- — O 3- tr. .'ii ,S < DISBURSEMENTS OF THE WAR 41 > < w n C3 1- - rt » oci £ x " , ca u . ^- . . >* u so en cu on " CI 10 lO 10 . r/-. . . 1*5 rt u on • \r. ■ ■ "2 u c3 on to 0) 00 '.*>•'.'. '. tC £ '"*- w NO _ . • C . • Fisca year 1898 c 00" 1—1 m o- o> 00 • •• • crcc r> \r. C •■<-> . 10 ^^ • ■ • • 00 10 ro 0_ • ON Fisca year 1897 a • • «n q i rO t^ N 1 -1- . l/~, — t^ (N On « w f : r -mo \ O ON M NO O <"} lO -tx X "". "". "~. " t^. 00 C3 CO CT) N -_ D X T t^ t^oo — On I ..C on M JJOO K -f On "- NO* NO* O 00 NO : if. ; ^ CO ."- O- I-O f iO ~ -1 1- SN O ^ NO 00 <-"• nC >-« ■"*• M f 3 C \ »— O 00 00 CI C rO tU C3 H t-l l-H f 4- r l H ON sS M H , - S 1-* u rt on >, - u rt On g - x - -. -• g D x [x, "~ >.« ON - 30 CO m _,vO _ - x -^ ~ 5S CO ON « o O C - 00 CO ID O rh tJ- co CO -I" t^OO O O i- ii M M 00 t^ i-i M 00~ i-TvO IDO" CI CI O ID -i CI i- On - — it S i. - H 'J Fiscal year 1901 NO O ON vO vO_ Fiscal year 1900 ID rO On 1- K t^ ID > -t in 1—, ID CI 00 CO 00" ID CI Fiscal year 1899 VO NO cOOO s — ID ,'- N N ki N N CI CI r^ -t ■<*■ Fiscal year 1898 00 Tt- ID * On t-; S ID -f .- C( M co ci t>. 0" **■ CO CO Fiscal year 1897 ft 00 VO ID ID CI ~ >Dx" ."- « O Hi OnvD ID CI 00_ CO CI ID vo" Fiscal year 1896 ONO Cl_ t^ S »D On > - <* d m CI ON CO q >D VO 00 CI June 1, 1894- March 31, 1896 CO ~_ s 0" «o ^J N id «IOCN -f ID vO CO c ID ID 0" O CI B 1 C - 1 - £ C > - ~r. "5 r- C c i. C disbursements of the war 43 Increase of Administrative Expenses Due to the War As already mentioned, the total increase of administrative expenses directly caused by the Sino-Japanesc War was 2 478»354 yen> disbursed as follows: Yen Foreign Office 307,831 Home Office 414,564 Treasury Office 1 ,614,246 Judicial Office 764 Communications Office 140,949 Total 2,478,354 The above expenses were only a little over 10.5 per cent of the total cost of the war; and the items of expense in detail for the above offices are tabulated on pages 44-46. An extraordinary session of the Imperial Diet was con- vened in October, 1894, at Hiroshima near the Imperial headquarters, and extra rewards were given to contributors to the war fund in money or materials and to those who relieved distressed families of soldiers at the front. 44 EXPENDITURES OF Mil. SI NO-JAPANESE WAR Expenses of Foreign Office Items 1894 1895 Total Yen 18,981 8,432 7.174 3.240 11,125 1,461 194,065 )'< n 6,927 6,013 12,941 2,016 23.472 1.550 3.455 6,979 Yen 25,908 14,445 1 lispatch of police to Korea. . . Allowance to diplomats and 20,115 5,256 Reconstruction of legation in 34,597 Repairing annex to legation in Korea 1,550 Reception of Chinese peace 4,916 201,044 fota] 244,478 63.353 307,831 Expenses of Legations and Consulates Names of legations and consulates Fiscal year 1894 Fiscal year 1895 Total Foreign office and legations abroad Yen 218,645 1,016 13,140 35 1,297 160 2,075 2,028 3,551 2,131 402 Yen 21,918 27,040 641 1,506 5,588 6,124 535 Yen 240,563 Legation in China 1,016 Legation in Korea 40,180 Consulate at Hongkong Consulate at Tientsin Consulate at Chefoo 35 1,297 160 Consulate at Shanghai Consulate at Fusan 2,716 3.534 Consulate at Seoul 9,139 8,255 Consulate at Gensan 937 Total 244,480 63,352 307,832 Expenses of Home Office Special Session Imperial Diet Korean affairs Extra rewards Year Home Office Metropoli- tan Police Office Prefec- tures Hokkaido Total 1894 1895 1897 [898 994 4,475 16,954 122,051 50,176 16,434 27,300 4,105 139,226 32,848 148,059 94.430 139,226 32,848 Total . . 994 21.429 172. 22~ 43,734 4.105 172,074 414,563 DISBURSEMENTS OF THE WAR Treasury Office 45 Items Fiscal year 1894 Fiscal year 1895 Fiscal year 1896 Fiscal year 1897 Total Extraordinary war expenditures (auditing Yen 1 1 ,969 Yen 11.687 12,241 r. n 38,897 Korean affairs: (A) Cabinet Dispatches to Imperial head- 14.022 93i 4.S79 4.099 5. 351 414 2.422 852 350 29.350 4.792 1.683 1,690 1,150 12,812 5,058 2,258 1,241 1.378 242 6.175 18.814 1.683 (B) Treasury Office Dispatches to Imperial head- 5,729 Dispatches to China and Korea . (C) Dispatch of Privy Council to Impe- 10,409 (D) Dispatch to the front of auditors of 3.663 (G) Manufacturing of military and com- 35,525 Total 62.370 38.479 349,779 Extraordinary session of the Imperial Diet: 22,412 25.794 Total 48,206 Furnishing of temporary Diet building: 12.729 12.386 12.386 Total 25.115 25,1 15 Rewards: (A; Manufacturing of extra decorations (B) Manufacturing of extra prize cups. 28,348 286,399 65.876 157.134 380.623 193.207 28.348 286.399 101,949 157.134 Managing allowance extra war funds 76,121 2,504 78.625 18,104 319.597 45.66s 2.890 3S6.256 1.082,345 162.301 1.601,558 Expenses of manufacturing public loan *> 12.688 » The expenditure of the Treasury t ion to the v. hlch sum In- cluded ull e erning the busim which were Legally l>ui nominally i the fiscal year of 1898 was for rewards and the makin g of pi . amounting 15.94 yen, and for printing public loan bonds in the same year: the following I m 1000: j.. b For the two ti^c.il years [899 and Judicial Office Fiscal year 1895 46 EXPENDITURES OF THK SI. \( (-JAPANESE WAR Communications Office* ( !ommunica1 inns office Administrative office of light houses. I I )] : DOSl .1 " Nagasaki I [iroshima oy a Kumamoto fotal iikI uh graph office. Yen 90,523 4i,4i5 2,094 2,985 4 2,337 837 754 140,949 i he outlay l>y the Communications Office during 1804 amounted to 140,949 yen, which repre- sented the increased expenses caused by the war, fractions of yen being omitted. CHAPTER III SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS The expenses of the Sino-Japanese War, as already out- lined, were about 235,000,000 yen in all; and of this sum the administrative outlay was mostly defrayed from reserve funds and surplus in the Treasury; hut the amount expended on the war being very large, the sources thereof are hereafter de- scribed in detail. The budget of revenue and expenditure relating to the expenses of the Sino-Japanese War, legally known as "extra war funds," was 250,000,000 yen; and the resources were mostly public loans and surplus funds in the Treasury, as well as a special account fund, but not from taxes. This was the beginning of war loans in Japan. Before entering upon a description of the main source of supply for war funds, it may be well to describe the budget and total accounts relating to the "special account for war purposes." Revenue Budget Fixed amount as receipt Amount received First section, war funds First subsection, war funds. . . . Yen 25,000,000 25,000,000 Yen 225,230,128 225,230,128 Yen 225,230,128 225,230,128 KXI'HNDITI'RKS First section, war funds. . . . First subsection, war funds. Budget Yen 25,000,000 25,000,000 Mixed sum by Imperial sanction )V/7 2iO.973.697 210,973,697 I'.i\ tnenl ordered Yen 200,475,508 200475,508 Of the expenditures above mentioned, the amount trans- ferred to General Budget Account was 9,037,494 yen, the 47 jS EXPENDITURES OF rHE S1NO-JAPANESE WAR unused portion of budget was 40,486,998 yen, and the unused portion of sum allowed by I mperial sanction was 1,460,698 yen. 'lhc total fixed sum of the above revenue stood as follows (details of expenditures to lie given later): Yen Treasury < Iffice 219,361,977 War ( Iffice 5.093.917 Naval 1 >ffice 774.234 225,230,128 The detailed items are as follows: Yen First section, war funds 225,230,128 First subsection, war funds: Yen Raising of public loan (Treasury Office) 1 16,804,927 Transfer of the surplus fund of Treasury (Treasury Office) 23,439,087 Contributed war funds (Treasury Office) 160,800 Contributed relief fund to War Office 2,210,650 Contributed relief fund to Naval Office 578,090 Miscellaneous receipts: Yen War Office 1,323.162 Naval Office 196,143 1,519,305 Receipts from occupied territory (War Office) 624,425 Receipts from Formosa and Pescadores Islands . . . 935,680 Transfers to Special Account (Treasury Office) .... 78, 957, 165 225,230,128 As stated above, the extra war funds amounted to such an immense sum, that it was necessary to make arrangement for a special account, separated from general revenue and ex- penditure. In October, 1894, by Law No. 24 the "Special Account for War Purposes Act" was promulgated, as follows: Article I. Finances for the extra war funds in regard to the affair with China and Korea shall be classified and adjusted separately from general revenue and expenditure. Article II. All revenue and expenditure for extra war funds from June I, 1894, until the termination of the war shall he regarded as included in one financial year. The above articles were based on Article XXX of the law of accounts, according to Law No. 4 of 1889, which says that "in case it is difficult to follow the provisions of the present law on account of special requirements, a special mode of pro- cedure may be allowed, but such special mode of treatment SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 49 must be effected by law." Therefore the expenditure allowed by this special law of finance was limited to war funds re- quired by the War Office and the Naval Office. This special account was wound up at the end of March, 1896, in accord- ance with the first article of Law Xo. 10 of the same year relating to the special account for war purposes. Since then all expenditure incurred by the War Office and the Naval Office for extra war outlay was included in the general budget accounts. Vote for war expenses Extra expenses for the carrying on of Korean affairs were to be defrayed from the second reserve fund in the fiscal year 1894 (the amount being 950,000 yen, that is to say, $473,100). This second reserve depends upon the 69th article of the Constitution of Japan which reads as follows: "In order to supply deficiencies, which are unavoidable, in the budget, and to meet requirements unprovided for in the same, a reserve fund shall be provided in the budget." Article 7 of "the law of Finance" explicitly states that "the second reserve shall be used to meet necessary expenses unprovided for in the budget." At the same time, articles 16 and 17 of the Rule of finance regulates its transaction and process. 1 low- ex er, the cost proved so enormous that the second reserve was insufficient. Thereupon in June it was decided by Imperial sanction to utilize for war expenses a surplus of 26, >,000 yen in the Treasury, 3,000,000 yen of which, as may be seen from details already given, was a loan t<> the Korean < rovern- inent. As the Chinese forces in Korea could not be put down by tin' troops of the Fifth Division, after the battles fought on July 25 and 20. at Phung Island and Songhwan respectively, mobilization took place, and the Imperial Declaration of War was issued on August 1. after which the Third Division was dispatched t<> the- front and the First Army Corps organized, thus extending the sphere of operations and increasing the outlay beyond the resources of tin sur- plus in the Treasury. 50 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR On August 15, 1894, Urgent Imperial Ordinance No. 143 was issued, in conformity with Article LXX of the Imperial Constitution, for the purpose of raising war funds, which provided for the transfer of funds included under special accounts, borrowing from banks or the raising of a public loan as an urgent measure. On the same day, by Imperial Ordinance No. 144, war loan regulations were issued, and it w .1- decided to incur a debt of 50,000,000 yen with interest at 6 per cent or under per annum, the first portion raised being the sum of 30,000,000 yen. On September 15, the Imperial headquarters were removed to Hiroshima; and on the 22d an extra session of the Imperial Diet was convened at the same place, which asked for a war budget of 150,000,000 yen, a bill being passed authorizing the notation of a public loan of 100,000,000 yen at less than 6 per cent per annum. The mode of flotation, terms of issue and period of redemption and others were entrusted to the Minister of Finance. Out of the total sum of 150,000,000 yen asked for, 59,996,- 885 yen had already been spent in urgent necessity, by Impe- rial sanction, beginning with June, 1894; and consequently, approval of this action was asked for at the special session of the Diet, in accordance with Article LXIV of the Imperial Constitution. It was a time when the nation's patriotism and public indignation had reached a state of high tension and no hesitation was had in giving approval to the necessary outlay for the war, the sums spent by Imperial sanction and the war loan being voted for with enthusiasm; and the war budget was promulgated on October 23, 1894. Moreover, at the eighth session of the Imperial Diet in February, 1895, the Lower House passed the following resolution with regard to war expenses: With respect to the issue of an Imperial Rescript for the subjugation of China we deem it proper to say that we think the attainment of the object of the war and the avengement of the nation's honor still a great way off; and therefore it is hereby resolved that further disbursement of war expenses shall be approved to any limit required. SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 5 1 During 1894 and 1895 the war was at its height and peace nowhere in sight, so that 96,290,000 yen out of the 150,000,000 yen approved by the Diet was spent by Imperial sanction in the eight months from June to January, 1896; and with an outlay of about 11,000,000 yen a month for army and navy, the balance of the sum voted by the Diet could scarcely suffice to June, 1895. The government estimated that the sum of at least 100,000,000 yen would be required from July to Decem- ber, 1895, and framed a supplementary budget accordingly. The measure was submitted to the Lower House on February 20 and authority for the raising of further war loans was given by both houses within a week, the supplementary war budget being issued on March 2, 1895. Disbursements The main resource for war funds was public loans and special contributions to war funds, special contributions for relief of army and navy men, transfers from surplus in the Treasury and from special account funds. The surplus from receipts and disbursements of the Treasury was deposited in the Bank of Japan either as a fixed or current account at reasonable interest, in accordance with Law No. 16, in June, 1894, at the beginning of the war; and disbursements from this account naturally caused an increase in the bank note issue, which was further accentuated by a government loan from the Bank of Japan and the transfer 1 >f the special account fund to the war fund. Thus the expenses of the war were covered by floating of loans and by increasing the issue of bank notes. Monthly receipts for the Special Account for War Purposes were as follows: ' 1 Table docs not in some parts correspond to the monthly receipt of war funds which will be described later, because it represents the sum received by the revenue officers, while the other was the sum paid into the cash office. Before the setting aside of a special account for war purposes, ihe allotted amount for war funds from the general account was paid out in the first month from the surplus in the Treasury — 26,000,000 yen — and the public loan and contributed relief funds are described in the following table according to the months they were actually received by the revenue officer. .s- 1 I MM NDITURl s nl Mil. SLNO-JAPANESE WAR iO iO N o ^o O nOOCO iO pi C i - ►" vO -TX lOOD iO -t C \0 O O OMO PI O O CO o -too — o> co <-> ~t ~t &• -t rrj O m O^ O e\_ go" o m m n" c cSfiCNC^iO lOOOO O PI X CO u~; ir, -t r^ ri — co C* "" CO o 6^ u m § u> n) u c*u C rt oj 3 ."-CO f— ' t/> o c[* « =~ si rt rt as o »i "> CJ 3-rj- 3 U fc o o „ L > 3 — : •r — U) V o L3 c > o © X m - d POiO — sO C PI OrO-rl-PI O PI pi o_ cj no t^c>p< mioo^x r^ IT, m" h dpivC*C O^lOfOM CO « — — rC-)-lCC^-> ^ i--3 > E-T3 e Pg w 3 rt vC X -1- « vO ■+ "". r»5 -1- t^ **■ lO 30 N -+ rO "JX_ 1C lO n o" ■^fo" 1^ -t PI l^N — ro "*■ PI PI X "-> ro PI ifivCvC hi VO Tf- w 00 X m\D O^C^^tfOO I^CX t-» O 0_ M t^- C_ C_ w p|_ VO O t>. ■* o *- ^f vo vo vc pj * ^rf'tn XMMCONMhN N WOm m . — _ j- 3 - ■■- ~ o 5 =.£ c c a o o S ex ^ '.'.'.'.. z z~ z c coco c c c o C O O <*2 IT, IT. (N PI pi io r^ ccccoccccccc- ccccccce-. — o t^x C — C> "3" P< W PI TffCX >- o ir; C lO <^ tC —" c" x~ OX -tN ^« N» ft M 1C-}- r-~ Tf 0_ O Pl_ t^ <-> c^O N PI O O C rO c" 0> M pT -- ■ z t x;z. = — - '- - ci? Sp a CS U »— — »— 3 3 — o - = k E 3 . - )!z;Q SUPPLY OF WAR FL'XDS 53 "+X X p r^. r^ ui ir-. ~ O r-- X o -t- 1>. i^ a «", r>. "". X X pi PI f f0Nf;O — D 3 *t t r- -»-X Ifl C C "". 3 — '1 li o l-l O ■^—PlOXI^CX po T,OiNM N N Ci 3\ ^ r i sC 3s "J U-3X o pi lO p 1/3 PI 1-1 C O C C X i<~. IO c o oj o cj "2 o o" o" C* ifl i^. o rC » ■ 00 t^ ■ ■ m •t ■ O oo ; . . .in _ IO o PI 1-0 Qs r lO IO «N pi <* • • . * -f : -f p pi VC o o PI f^ PI C PI C i-'". t - X Cs 1/-. rf> -t" r^ O l>. 11 O sO r^ C 1^ :; rO PI t-. o r-» ■<*• — pi 5 £ po SO <-C (Oh *m (H m O C\ M ON PI vO if, i/; ir.oo O PI "2 -i-c iON3\c^-tM o o o OOP! i^O PI -+- cr •* PI rO Os «" 00* oo Pi" 8 00 o" o ""■ rOvO O O O O O o X r^ 5 3 i-i ►■ _x_ cd o_ o o «o r /: 0> ^ pT» in fo ji fi io -f O -t io po - c t^-rc oo»c -t: - o 9 -1- X ir. m m"h ts o* > C b _f u|ji ~ a u — — L C - — > — ■ si u 5 3 Z = D "? >-*-»< J5 54 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR The methods of raising war funds may be classified as follows: Private Subscriptions to Public Loans and War Funds Date 1894 July August. . . September . October. . . November . December. 1895 January. . February. March. . . . April May June July August. . . September. October. . . November. December . 1896 January . . . February . . March April May June July August. . . September. October. . . November. December . Public loan Total 233,618,653 Yen 2,500,000 500,000 5,241,000 7,241,300 2,795,ooo 6,480,100 9,645,900 10,032,400 13,297,200 10,721,700 9,120,000 88,490 26,310 322,860 1,051,170 2,749-989 25,861,135 843.865 1,652,000 1 ,438,000 1,015,000 2,163,000 679,500 942,000 405,808 116,804,926 Contributed to war funds Yen 100,000 60,800 Contributed to relief fund of army and navy 160,800 321,600 Yen 5.836 175.238 347.444 420,371 254,546 276,854 280,688 321,011 324,163 166,792 106,095 26,046 22,136 14,262 24,676 9,604 4,782 3,478 964 1,066 1,011 205 307 29 53 964 121 2,788,741 5.577.483 Total Yen 5,836 175.238 2,847,444 920,371 5,595.546 7,578,954 3.075.688 6,801,111 9,970,063 10,199,192 13,403,295 10,747,746 9,142,136 102,752 50,986 332,464 1,055.952 2,753.467 964 1,066 25,862,146 844,070 1,652,307 1,438,029 1,015,053 2,163,964 679,621 942,000 405,808 119,754,467 239.5i7.736 SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 55 War Expenses Met by Increasing the Issue of Bank Notes of Bank of Japan ■ Date 1894 June July September October. . November December . 1895 January . . February . March . . . April May June July August. . . September October. . November December . 1896 January. . February . March . . . April May June July August. . . September October. . November Total . Surplus of Treasury Yen 26,000,000 1 19,086 23.439.086 Miscellaneous receipts Yen 1,806 10.566 83,202 5.045 11,361 1 1. 216 19,670 32.743 146,969 50,293 99,5i4 15.502 183.959 272,832 126,330 63,242 53.077 51,703 54.070 81. 711 102,406 1,163 20,237 19,008 1,679 Borrowed from Bank of Japan 1 en 6,000,000 12,500,000 19.530,000 18,420,000 22,530,000 20,500,000 17,500,000 14,000,000 12,500,000 12,500,000 12.500,000 18,390,000 25,000,000 33,100,000 41,500,000 42,500,000 41,270,000 37.900,000 41,240,000 440.380,000 Transfers from Treasury Yen 2.553.377 8,814,025 7.970,645 16.724,798 16,048,649 22,368,991 25,077.224 24,195.419 22,661,037 20.727,592 26,748,677 29,080,730 32.412.10.1 31.534.407 28,710,373 34.930,525 4I,773.o6l 26,7 ' 0, !'■-• [6,107,780 3,102,036 438,252,092 Transfers from spe- cial ac- count fund Yen 9.020,000 52.020.000 . - 7.665.676 4.613.948 1,356.585 78,957.165 War scrip issued 3.780.000 3.780.000 3.780.000 3.780,000 1. 886.816 1.293.606 820.168 104 104 '"4 104 26.444.578 a The sum borrowed from the Bank of Japan, the transfers from the Treasury and the issuing of war scrip were temporary measures tomeet deficits, and aitei Ai>ril 1. t8o6, these were redeemed by public loan and by transfer of special account fund, which accounts for some items being du- plicated. The revenue from occupied territory amounted to 024,425 yen, or about $310,964, which, on account of having been levied after March, 1896, is not scheduled above. The monthly receipt of war funds stood as shown in the table at the top of next page, but in case the amount of revenue should not correspond to the above tables reference had better be made to the former. As previously described, the amount of revenue for war funds does not always correspond to payment for war ex- penses; and such being the case, whenever a deficit would ha> e occurred, money was borrowed from the Bank of Japan, or 5<) I XPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Mom in. \ Revenue and Expenditures, 1894-1896 Date [894 June 6 J 11 1 > 30. August September October November December 1895 January February Match April May June July August September October November December 1896 January February March April-November Total Reven uc Yen 26,000,000 3.395-5^5 6,579,153 7,588,052 3,161,151 6,805,365 6,992,033 10,201,408 13,422,961 10,780,339 9,289,459 152,984 151. 841 346,675 1,239,680 3,026,534 127,291 64.316 26,548 278 89.357,043 225,230,128 Expenditures War Office Naval Office Total Yen 4.789,377 5,945. 4<>7 7,970,252 11,988,463 12,931,275 10,999,451 9,262,790 8,550,979 13,696,459 7,974,876 7,953.360 6,215,641 5.651.285 4.357.157 6,683,723 8,406,199 6,940,476 6,980,463 6,096,322 4,742,457 7,35i,52i 976,652' 164,520371 Yen 474,606 1,705,441 i.795. OI 3 3.27L294 6,408,527 2,775,220 1.542,514 1,688,237 1,365,916 1,934,765 1,087,796 1,530,316 1,228,999 1,265,465 824,167 1,288,730 1,089,670 1,580,345 835.667 529.785 764.158 968,509 35955,140 Yen 5,272,982 7.650,937 9.765,265 15,259,757 i9,339,8oi 13,774,671 10,805,304 10,239,216 15,062,375 9,909,641 9,041,156 7,745.957 6,880,283 5,622,622 7,507,890 9.694.929 8,030,146 8,560,809 6,931.989 5,272,242 8,115,679 8,i43 a 200,475,508 •After April, 1896. revenue is not tabulated by the month, since it was an adjustment account after the end of the fiscal year; but these amounts show that the fixed sum of refunding exceeds that of payment. appropriated from surplus in the Treasury, or by the issue of war scrip; and these temporary measures were repaid after April 1, 1896, by raising public loans and the transfer of the special account fund, which transactions will be described hereafter. In regard to the above, the government used bank notes and copper coins as far as possible to meet extra expenses, and thus prevented a diminution of specie as well as the danger of a financial panic. The total amount paid out for war from June, 1894, to the end of March, 1896, was 200,483,651 yen, the following currency being employed: SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS Currency Expended for War Purposes, i 894-1 896 57 Amount Percentage Bank notes and copper coin Silver dollars Subsidiary silver coins Silver bullion Mexican dollars Sycees War scrip Total 183,981,744 11,651,482 2,60I,028 300,000 850,000 1.099.293 IO4 200,483,651 91.8 5 - ■ i 2 0.4 5 With regard to war scrip, it may be necessary to say some- thing as to how it was used. Had bank notes been used in the theater of war, the paper currency would accordingly have had to be increased and in consequence there might have been a considerable withdrawal of specie. To avoid this, war notes of 1.5 and 10 taels, as well as of 5 sen, 2 sen, and one-half sen, were issued. It was found, however, that to circulate both war notes and bank notes in the same region was inconvenient for transactions; and so when the Japanese forces were about to invade the province of Chihli they were provided with war notes to the face value of 3,780,000 yen, equal to 2,700,000 taels, for use in that region. Peace was so soon restored, how- ever, that it was found that only 103.60 yen of the war scrip had been used. The supply of war funds has already been outlined in a very general way, but each item in detail will be given later on. Expenditure of the Surplus in the Tri \m ry and i hi Temporary Making Up of Deficits The budget for army and navy outlay during the war with China was calculated at the sum of 250,000,000 yen, for the greater part of which the government had to depend on public loans, the surplus in the Treasury for the fiscal year of [893, the transfer of indemnity and other sources of income being comparatively of minor importance, as shown in the following table : 58 I XPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Yen Percentage I reasurj surplus, fiscal year 1893 23,439,086 10.4 Public loans 116,804,926 51 .9 I ransferol indemnity 78,957.165 35.0 Other receipts 6,028,950 2.7 Total 225,230,127 100. o Although the surplus in the Treasury could be used im- mediately at the outset of the war, the public loan turned in 4,326,108 yen in monthly average from September, 1894, to November, 1896; and the transfer of indemnity was carried out after April, 1896. So that during this time revenue and expenditure did not often correspond, which will be explained later. Before the Sino-Japanese War, the annual accounts showed a yearly surplus, owing to the negative policy, and the actual results for the years before the war stood as follows: Fiscal year Yen 1889 16,974,307 1890 24,343,951 1891 19.675,597 1892 24,727,171 1893 29,187,509 Total 1 14.908,535 The surplus of the fiscal year 1893 was 29,187,508 yen; and 5,748,422 yen of this sum was transferred to the next fiscal year, so that 23,439,086 yen was transferred to the war fund, which facilitated our war movement. Although at the out- break of war two or three special accounts were added to the surplus of 23,439,086 yen described above, so that it amounted to some 26,000,000 yen as war fund (including 439,086 yen added in November), 3,000,000 yen out of the amount were loaned to the Korean Government. Therefore it was in the end the same as mentioned at first. And although the war expenses were defrayed by the transfer of the surplus in the Treasury, from the outbreak of war to September, in a short time there \\ as a deficit. SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS Monthly Receipts and Disbursements, i 894-1 896 59 1894 June 6-July 31 . . August September October November December 1895 January February March April May June July August September October November December 1896 January February March April-November a Total Receipts Yen 26,000,000 3.395.5 6 5 6,579.153 7,588,052 ,161,151 805,365 .992,033 ,201,408 422,961 780,339 ,289,459 152.984 151.841 346.675 239,680 026,534 127,291 64,316 26,548,278 89.357,043 225,230,128 Disbursements Yen 5,272,982 7,650,937 9.765.265 15.259.757 i9.339.8oi 13,774,671 10,805.304 10,239,216 15,062,375 9,909,641 9.041,156 7,745.957 6,880,283 5,622,622 7,507,890 9.694.929 8,030,146 8,560,809 6.931.989 5,272,242 8,115,680 8,i43 b 200,475,508 » After April, 1896, accounts were not reckoned by the month, as it was an adjustment account after the end of the fiscal year. b Fixed sum of refunding exceeded that of payment. From June, 1894, to May, 1896, the highest total shortage was 83,043,165 yen, which occurred in February, 1896, to meet which transfers were at once made from the Treasury, or loans were had from the Bank of Japan, or else war scrip was issued to make temporary adjustment. The following table will indicate the details of the making up of temporary deficits. Although the sum borrowed from the Bank of Japan will be described later, it is added here for the sake of convenience: 60 I XPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Means ob Meeting Deficits in War Fund, 1894-1896 Date 1894 June July August . . . September October. . November December 1895 January. . February . March . . . April May June July August . . . September October. . November December 1896 January. . February . March. . . April May Total Total deficits in war fund Yen 8,553.377 21,314,025 27,500,645 35.I44-798 38,578,649 46,648,991 46,357,224 41.975.419 38,941,037 36,531,861 42,001,498 49,357,547 58,705,800 65,496,266 71,030,541 77.835.239 83,043,165 64,610,566 57,347,884 3.102,138 Transfers from Treasury Temporary loan from Bank of Japan 914,076,670 Yen 2,553.377 8,814,025 7,970,645 16,724,798 16,048,649 22,368,991 25,077,224 24,195,419 22,661,037 20,727,592 26,748,677 29,080,730 32,412,194 31.534.497 28,710,373 34,930,525 41,773,061 26,710,462 16,107,780 3,102,036 438,252,092 Yen 6,000,000 12,500,000 19,530.000 18,420,000 22,530,000 20,500,000 17,500,000 14,000,000 12,500,000 12,500,000 12,500,000 18,390,000 25,000,000 33,100,000 41,500,000 42,500,000 41,270,000 37,900,000 41,240,000 449,380,000 Amount of war scrip issued Yen 3,780,000 3,780,000 3,780,000 3,780,000 3,304,269 2,752,821 1,886,817 1,293,606 861,769 820,168 404.7H 104 104 104 102 26,444,578 After June, 1896, there was no further shortage. SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 6l Ratio of Means of Meeting Deficit^ in War Fund, [894-1896 Date 1894 October. . November December 1895 January. . February . March. . . April .... May June July August. . . September October. . November December 1896 January. . February . March . . . April .... May Transfers from Treasury 29.9 4'4 29.0 44 9 503 41 3 28.1 100 o Loans from Bank of Japan 70.1 58.6 71 .0 52 5* 43 37 33 32 34 29 37 1- 50 58 Issue of war scrip 8.1 8.1 9.0 9 7 9i 6-5 3-8 2 .2 13 1 .2 0-5 As may be seen from the above, the temporary deficit was met by transfers from the Treasury and loan- from the Bank of Japan. So much then for the summary of war finance. Issue of Public Loan- The public loan floated to cover the expenses of the war with China and affairs in Korea was named the "War Loan," and the sum of legal issue anticipated was in all about 230,- 000,000 yen; but only 124,920,0003^ was put on the market, as may be seen from the statements on pages 62 63. A necessary disposition of finance with regard to Korean affairs was promulgated by Imperial Emergency Ordinance No. 143 on August 14, 1894, as follows: "The government is authorized to float a public loan for the purpose of meeting the expenses of Korean affairs." War loan regulations were then promulgated by Imperial Ordinance No. 144 on August 02 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR "O 41 O 3 A 1- 3 tn L. js c 3 C a*a 0- Bought by Bank of Japan ac- cording to spe- cial regulations -o C c o rt • - is 3 cj bfl Imp. Ord. No. 144, Aug. 15, 1894 Laws Nos. 25 and 195, Treas. Dept., Oct. 23, 1894 Law No. 8, Mar. 2, 1895; Ord. No. 2, Treas. Dept., Mar. 4, 1896 Ord. No. 3, Treas. Dept., Mar. 4, 1896 Imp. Ord. No. 137, Oct. 2, 1896; Ord. No. 3, Treas. Dept., Oct. 4, 1896 CD e • -i en -a g rt E it 1° 8; Sept. 20, 1894- June 30, 1895 7; Dec. 25, 1894- June 30, 1895 8; Mar. 31-Oct. 31, 1896 Amount authorized Yen 30,000,000 50,000,000 10,000,000 25,000,000 10,000,000 "o c .tJ.2 E td — . u c c Sept. 10-13, l8 94 Dec. 11-15, 1894 Mar. 16-21, 1896 c \ 'Z b ■J 2d Subscription (2d issue) 3d Subscription (4th issue) .... 4th Issue V e? or c « C 5 SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 63 u ed 3 B •s ■5 ■s c *r? c ~ -1 la i_ u o> O M /. - R * r i U) DO BO :-e 8 _- 2 — ■ — X "gag Q w 'C 3 3 a* 8. a S _ ; 3; J2 t/3 J CD x _ V. ~^ '^T a .9* x_ k k •7. C i_ . u '- > c 1 ■§ X L X 09 - > - ~ u 3 c g .3 3.3 3 "H x — x u B u g — '- 3 CJ -2 ~r. t C 3 +3 K 3 cc 1- u •i 5 ~ x u X 5~ ~ 1. — 3 C 1- w ■*■ - T = 3— v ■^: x — T3 /. _ fg|§ — 2^ — c •- 2 |g 2"* z~ ~ y - c— a- Z ~ 2 * X U -'- ~- c ■ - X " _~ ~ — (X W - - - ~ - — PI O pi 1- m c _ t>. PO Wi 00 8 OV M PI 00 XT', gv ■* ' *J pi q; t-» q 3 > S pi* PO cf - "\ •* -f pi" r-^. £'3 c u ^ 8 O to q PO /- q ^f - dj 30 00 PI -t in Ov vo" IC p7 PI c z O O ■— c 8 3 T> 10 O 10 0.0 IT) in t^ PI O t^ (>. c S, 10 Q rC vo "* ■ ed nj « ~ Id « h ~. s i i P^ C S - O -C r- £ - O JH H H r- J— H h r- H In" a> 3 U5 ^ 43 3 IT. 3" x ~ -3 ^, H ai ed 3- 3 •3 pi v o 09 tj •3 «i 3 a PO J£ B B c 3 3 3 O 3 — ! -3 ■ u -s; c 3 ed vo 15 3 1- £ £ krj u 64 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR 15, 1894, when it was decided to float a public loan by in- stalments to the limit of 50,000,000 yen. This was the beginning of war loans in Japan. The war loan regulations fixed only the amount of the subscription, the period of redemption, the rate of interest and the lime of payment. All other details of the loan were to be based on the consolidated public loan regulations by Imperial Ordinance No. 66 of October 16, 1886; and the war loan regulations were as follows: War loan regulations Article i. War loans shall be floated gradually to the limit of 50,000,000 yen by Imperial Ordinance No. 143. Art. 2. The interest on the loan shall be less than 6 per cent per annum, and shall be paid twice yearly, in the month of June and December, until the redemption of the principal. Art. 3. The principal shall be redeemed within fifty years from the sixth year after issue. Art. 4. The subscriptions to the loans, the amount of issue, the price, rate of interest, the period of subscription, the number of limes of instalment for subscription and other details shall be fixed by the Minister of Finance. Art. 5. The delivery of public loan bonds, prescriptions in regard to payment of principal and interest, the management of bonds, and all other details not fixed by this regulation shall be arranged ac- cording to the Consolidated Public Loan Regulations promulgated by Imperial Ordinance Xo. 66 of the year IT" The subscriptions received on the above basis comprised the first war loan; and the method of subscription was an- nounced 1»\ Notification No. 32 issued by the Treasury De- partment on August 17, 1894, the amount called for being, as already explained, 30,000,000 yen. They were issued at par and the security money was to be 10 per cent of the face value, the security to be transferred to the first payment, and the rest to be paid tip in seven instalments from November 16, 1894, to the end of June, 1895. SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 65 Method of Payment fob Bonds of First War Loan Payments [894 [895 Yen First to September 20 < l( tober 16-31 \u\ I'llll n I" H1-3O February n> 28 March 16-31 April 16-30 \l.i\ [6-3I June 16-30 Second Third Fourth 10 Fifth Sixth 10 Seventh 20 Eighth 10 "Transferred from security. The first war loan happened to be placed on the market at a time when money in both Osaka and Tokyo was showing the customary stringency of the season, and the daily in- terest fixed by the Tokyo Bankers' Club was 2 sen, 8.4 rin, or 10.022 per cent, and loans from the Bank of Japan were then 2 sen, 20. rin, or 8.03 per cent. The daily discount rate of securities payable in Tokyo was 2 sen, 1 rin, which is equal to 7.665 per cent, while the daily rate of discount of securities payable in another place was 2 sen, 3 rin, or 8.395 per cent. The minimum and maximum of interest in Tokyo and Osaka at that time was as follows: Interest Charges in Tokyo \m> Osaka 1 !lassification of amount loaned on security Modi hs Tok\o Osaka 1 [ighest 1 owes! Average 1 Iigh< -1 1 OWI -! \\ erage Yen Per Per Per Per Per Per cent criil cent ccni cent ecu! IO0 1000 Vug. 1 [27 959 1 034 1 351 1 i;,j I ^41 Sept. 1 [07 971 1 056 1 J So 1 010 I [22 1,000-10,000 . . . Aug. 1 076 923 1 003 I 278 1 050 1 [32 Sept. 1 051 934 1 003 1 [63 96] I 059 Al"i\ c m.ooo . . . Aug. 987 ,, 882 926 1 J.J1 I 059 I 132 Sept. 98] 875 934 1 165 1 009 1 090 The market price of 5 per cent national bonds depreciated as follows: 66 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Depreciation of 5 per cent National Bond-. Date I-oans Kinroku Naval Consolidated August, 1894 September, 1894 Yen 100.38 99-57 Yen 95 90 99 56 Yen 100.49 100.21 To undertake the flotation of a pubic loan for so large a sum as 30,000,000 yen was without precedent in Japan. Con- sequently the government, and the public as well, regarded the outcome with some misgiving. But fortunately the loyalty and patriotism of the nation overcame all difficulties and the subscriptions amounted to no less than 77,002,650 yen, the highest bid per hundred of face value being 142.44 yen, while other bids were 125 and 120 yen. The authorities therefore decided to accept applications for subscriptions above par to the extent of 11,627,850 yen, and at par to the amount of 18,372,150, or 30,000,000 yen in all. The sum of actual receipts amounted to 30,063,372 yen, but as there were a few applicants who did not take up the amount applied for and forfeited their deposit money the total was thus affected, yet the amount subscribed was thereby reduced by only 2,200 yen, while the reduction in the actual receipts was no more than 1,855 y en - This signal success was ob- tained through the people's patriotism and public indignation. The second loan, which was issued in accordance with Law No. 25 of October 23, 1894, was P ut on the market in Novem- ber, 1894. The law reads as follows: "In order to defray the war expenses in connection with China and Korea the govern- ment is hereby authorized to raise a public loan gradually at less than 6 per cent interest; and the necessary details, such as methods, agreements, subscriptions and period of redemption, shall be fixed by the Minister of Finance." On November 22, 1894, by Departmental Order No. 19, the Treasury floated a loan of 50,000,000 yen at 5 per cent interest, the notice concerning subscriptions being based on SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 6? Departmental Order No. 40, issued on the 22d of the same month by the Treasury. The loan was issued at 95 per 100 yen of face value, the security money to be transferred to subscription as first payment, and the balance to be paid up in six instalments from January 16, 1895, to the end of June of the same year. The period of application for subscription was limited to four days only, from December 11 to 15, other details being the same as in the case of the first loan. The instalments were to be paid up at the following rate per hundred yen of face value: Method of Payment for Bonds of Second War Loan Payments 1 894- 1 895 Yen First to December 25 January 16-31 February 16-28 March 16-31 April 16-30 May 16-31 June 16-30 10* 10 Third . 10 Fourth 10 Fifth 20 Sixth *5 20 » Transferred from security. Applications for subscriptions amounted to 90,301,300 yen, being 40,301,300 yen in excess of the issue called for. The highest bid was 120 yen. The government then decided to accept, first, applications for subscriptions above par to the amount of 22,119,850 yen, and, next, from among applicants at less than par, but more than 95 per 100 yen, the sum of 7,924,000 yen; and 19,955,150 yen from among applicants at par, making 50,000,000 in all. As it was about the end of the year, the money market was somewhat tight, and the market price of the national bonds tended toward depreciation. Nevertheless the outcome was successful beyond expectation. This was due largely to the strength of the government's financial credit and the inherent economic power as well as to the patriotic feelings of the people. The third loan was issued according to Law No. 8 of March 2, 1895, which says: "In order to meel expenses in regard to the war with China the government is hereby authorized to float by degrees a public loan to the limit of 100,000,000 yen us I M'l MMTURKS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR at interest of less than 6 per cent; and the necessary details as to price, method of flotation, agreement and period of subscrip- tion and redemption shall be left to the Minister of Firtance." On March 4, 1896, in accordance with Order No. 2 of the Treasury Department it was decided to call for a loan of 10,000,000 yen at 5 per cent interest; and in accordance with Announcement No. 13 issued by the Treasury, the date of payment for subscriptions was to be from April 16 to the end of October, 1896, in seven instalments, the period for applica- tions to be from March 16 to 21, all other details to be the same as in the first issue. The rate of payment for instalments was as follows: Method of Payment for Bonds of Third War Loan Payments 1896 Yen First to March 31, April 16-30 May 16-31 June 16-30 July 16-31 August 17-31 September 16-30 October 16-31 I0 a 10 Third 20 10 Fifth 10 sixth 20 10 Eighth 10 a Transferred from security. As the war was now over and the nation busily engaged in post-bellum enterprises, many hopeful undertakings were being started and the money market was showing considerable stringency. Consequently the amount subscribed was only 1 1578,050 yen, the highest bid being 103, the applications above par reaching 1,026,850 yen and those at par 551,200. Therefore to make up the deficiency, 5,000,000 yen was trans- ferred from the indemnity account, and the Bank of Japan advanced the sum of 3,420,000 yen on these bonds. The general features of each of the loans having been out- lined above, the loans may be tabulated as on pages 69-70. During the periods of subscription for the first and second loans the war was in progress, and news of victory was con- stant ly in the air. but no one of course knew as yet just what would lie the final outcome. Yet it was quite evident that the nation was being worked up to a high state of excitement SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 6 9 OS _ - 500«1 "■. 1 - c a C C C C "". ur C 5 z -r 3 C C "OON 000 1- -0 ^ cr- pi ""- O "0 r i T ~ X 09 ~ ON ^" l/_ M c r -r O . - M ef -f i^l PI 1^ 0" pO ro c C fZ -0 1 - C 'O i^. t^. N -f 0" t~- 1 - 1- -t- C*3 3 X X O O O O C 00 Z Z - z c C DC z B cd O POO c • a z 00 c C "". 10 Z ■ C z 1/3 ,_] s C — X — — m c • - - p<_ — K <" Q cfl O 0" >— r^ ri c a °_ °_ 9. c z IE BO w 0" 6 _______ z X c c S - 5 c - C O O PI c O -0 u - a g uo ir > pi C ~o -0 n ~ c r r m g po -1-00 — C po 00 . —* > m" «" a; z - 00 c ►*» 00 — z z '0 tO M M Z "~. vq 00 000" n" 6 6 1^ c^o ci m, -r -t- 00c -rex z z - c -r c Z Z Z P c c O O O M O C c PI •no uo -t- C O C UO z Z 1 -. ~ C X X — « — PO ~ ►*> r-» (n O N PO u c vC °_ r ?°. c c E tC in t-T 0" r^ 3 SVO M PO -f PO a, W y U T" ■3 u >- _- 0." *- tfl •/ tl B _r c C_-._= C *■* - 1 • • 3 t. — — - - (fi g 2 * 3 2 -J c « = - n.y_ i « c. c 5 _ __ «■ ■- _: — - _ — • - rt e e w « s. <■• H «- a t£ 6 .§2 22-£o£ . — — « S r 1 "G « 5 > t _ 5 9r * S 9) O r- O ^ - — 3 — C C— > gH < < a j < JHC-< x> rf t/3 rf 70 EXPENDITURE OI- Till-: SI \< (-JAPANESE WAR o o o o o o o i/5 IC O "0 "^ "j O O io 4J OvO»N >-* O^ "+ C£ "+ q; c S IT, N "* lO 1^ " O-- •*■ CO 3 0 fln . i- f<3 o o -4 < iO ro o" -c u J3 - M rt-t ■ l^lON o H C) rO^O m >m M vO 6 q. M £ cf rT I/l oooooooo o 2 o>oociocco o O c "t^^c^incx^ rO 3 O g « u~ ,-T o" r-^ r^ r-^ c£ c 03 O vO C£vO GO " O E < J fO iO o> Cm 0* -o c < o rj- Q\00 i- IO00 rD <*: HI O^- i- - C5v£> UO o 6 "I" M N" o^ £ M W O" rO z t^. r^ o M 1-1 50 o o o o o o o § iA. r^ t-^ rO ci \D i o IO 2 H c 3 O E < ri \fi c O Q 03 C — : rr> tJ- r^ 4-J I/) 1* 00 O "* O CM i- o rO (N (N O "+ O ■ \r> 6 1^ „ _ _ oo o_ ^ w vo c> !/) • c • o • •w U3 3 _0 .-'-3 §2 u u ,;1T m o 03 c ( l* 3 o r. nanci verni 5. E o "C tn nine and self- :als. s an dual __ o a c C ' K O i 1 i _ c > ' .2 .'a h SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 71 and indignation, and liberal contributions for the relief of soldiers as well as many other patriotic works were under- taken, with the result that the loan was popular beyond all expectation, especially as compared with loans raised in time of peace. Even the very poor who could not be expected to have more than would keep them, applied for subscriptions out of their small savings and by dint of the most careful frugality. Accordingly, the number of subscribers to the first loan was 119,015; to the second loan, 173,051; and the average sum subscribed for in the first loan was 647 yen; and in the second loan, 521 yen. The difference was, there- fore, as far apart as heaven and earth as compared with loans issued in time of peace, the average then being 3,005 yen per subscriber. On account of the number of applications from small sub- scribers being so numerous there were naturally some deferred payments, the interest on which amounted to 7,3 1 3.7 1 yen for the three issues. Moreover, the regulations concerning con- solidated bonds required that applications which were not paid up should become invalid and the security money for- feited together with the amounts paid up. For this reason the fixed amount subscribed was slightly reduced. This being the case, the actual sum of the war bonds issued was 89,996,- 500 yen in all. The actual sum of receipts was still further modified by interest on deferred payments, the account being as shown in the table on page 72. 1 The public loans heretofore described were issued directly to the public by so-called general subscription. At the same time a war loan of 35,000,000 yen was subscribed tor by extraordinary special issue based upon Article VI, paragraph 1 By regulations of consolidated bonds the paid up sums of those failing to com- plete their payments were forfeited; and, in this way, of the first issue 20 yen of security money and 90 yen of the first instalment was forfeited, 190 yen of the second instalment and 45 yen of the third instalment. In the second issue 65 yen among subscribers to the first instalment, 50 yen of the second, 6oyen of the third, 60 yen of the fourth, and 30 yen of the fifth instalment, were forfeited. The difference between par and above par price which was paid up in the first issue was 12.80 yen and 4.04 yen in the second. However, in the first. .1- there was a case in which only the security money was paid and not 0.30 yen ol the difference mentioned previously, a fractional Bum of 0.30 yen did not go into the actual receipt. ;j EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Receipts from War Loa\> First issue Second issue Third issue- Total Subscription: Amount issued " deferred Yen 30,000,000 2,200 Yen 50,000,000 1,300 Fen 10,000,000 Yen 90,000,000 3,500 Total 29,997,800 30,065,227 i,855 49,998,700 47,639,822 970 10,000,000 10,001,258 89,996,500 Receipts: Amount received " deferred 87,706,307 2,825 Total 30,063,372 3,134 47,638,852 4,044 10,001,258 134 87,703,482 Amount received: Interest on deferred 7,312 Total 30,066,506 47,642,896 10,001,392 87,710,794 2, of the amendment to the regulations with regard to con- solidated bonds, promulgated by virtue of Imperial Ordinance No. 46, issued on June 16, 1888, which declares that "the Minister of Finance is authorized to issue bonds after the price of the Consolidated Loan bonds is fixed, in accordance with the current market price, without having recourse to general subscriptions, the bonds to be delivered to the Bank of Japan; but the amount and the price of the bonds so issued must be published by the Minister of Finance on the day after issue." In regard to the above it may be said that the Minister of Finance fixes the price of such bonds as he may think proper, in accordance with the market price of the bonds of the same kind which he has issued before. One of the extraordinary special loans was based upon Imperial Ordinance No. 137, of October 1895 which says: "The grant of a lump sum may be had from the Treasury for war purposes by delivering bonds at par to the Bank of Japan who will deliver them to purchasers according to con- venience, no transaction to be for less than 50 yen." This loan was issued in instalments at 5 per cent interest to the SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 73 limit of 10,000,000 yen, which was part of the 100,000,000 yen loan previously arranged to be issued in conformity with Law- No. 25 of October 23, 1894, known as the Kosho Loan, based on Order No. 3 of the Treasury Department, October 4, 1895. As the said loan was to be issued in place of a grant from the Treasury, either the War or the Naval Office applied to the Bank of Japan as necessity required, and the bank applied to the Minister of Finance, who then issued in accordance with the second clause of article 6 of the Consolidated Bond Regulations and delivered the bonds to the Bank of Japan, and the bank paid the money into the Treasury. Moreover, as to certain parts of the war budget up to March, 1896, it was known as an extraordinary account, as both the War and the Naval Office decided to purchase the bonds above named. The total amount of issue was 9,924,250 yen; and the amount of actual receipts was 9,734,205.15 yen, being 9.132,756 yen for the War Office, and 791,500 for the Naval Office. But in regard to the purchase the special account for war purposes amounted to 4,102,394.50 yen and the amount not issued was 75.750 yen. Another extraordinary special issue, being the fourth loan, was for 25,000,000 yen in face value of bonds issued, taken up by employing funds from the Deposits Section of the Treasury. The details with regard to the loan are given on page 74. Loans The loans for extraordinary war expenses were based on Imperial Emergency Ordinance No. 143. issued on August 13, 1894, which says: "In order to meet the expenses of Korean affairs the government is hereby authorized to borrow money, as an urgent measure, from the Bank of Japan." Although this power was not used at the time, it authorized the govern- ment to make up a temporary shortage by borrowing from the central bank to help out the war funds. Again, by virtue of Law No. 25 issued on October 23, 1894, ,,lr government floated a public loan to the limit of 100,000,000 yen at less than 6 per cent interest, at the same time borrowing money 74 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Fourth War Loan Issues Date Amount of issue Price Amount actu- ally issued 1895 Yen Yen Yen Third Oct. 16 90,000 100.50 90,450 " Oct. 25 1 50,000 100.20 150,300 u Oct. 30 40,000 100 30 40,120 ii Oct. 31 30,000 100.30 30,090 " Nov. 8 400,000 100.30 401,200 " Nov. 14 50,000 100.70 50,35O a Nov. 19 262,500 101.10 265,388 il Nov. 28 328,000 101.90 334.232 ii Dec. 9 60,000 1 02 .60 61,560 " Dec. 13 250,000 102.50 250,250 ii Dec. 25 2,037,000 101 50 2,067,555 ii Dec. 27 350,000 101.40 354,900 1896 ii Apr. 2 50,000 98.90 49.450 " Apr. 6 30,000 98.90 29,670 June 29 500,000 100.20 501,000 II Sept. 26 300,000 98.70 296,100 1 1 Dec. 16 500,000 98.36 491,800 1897 II Feb. 26 300,000 99-49 298,470 " .Mar. 3 600,000 99.04 594,240 " Mar. 26 400,000 99.14 396,560 1 1 Oct. 14 600,000 95-83 574-98o Dec. 21 1898 1 ,000,000 93-15 931,500 " Feb. 7 45.000 9348 42,066 " Mar. 12 1 ,200,000 91.32 1,095,840 " Mar. 30 3,000 89.94 2,698 " Oct. 24 48,000 92.51 44.405 Dec. 28 1899 57-750 92.98 53.696 ii Mar. 15 28,000 95-84 26,751 " Mar. 28 130,000 94.81 123,253 Oct. 13 20,000 95 8 19,096 1900 ii Mar. 27 60,000 92.84 55.704 Sept. 28 3,000 90.71 2,721 Oct. 15 2,000 90.51 1,810 Total 9,924,250 9,728,205 Fourth Mar. 4. 1896 25,000,000 100.00 25,000,000 Total ^4,924.250 34,728,205 SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS /0 from the Bank of Japan, the amount being used for extraor- dinary war expenses. By virtue of Law Xo. 8 of March 2, 1895, the government borrowed money under the same conditions as above. A loan of 20,500,000 yen was raised by authority of Law No. 25 and a loan of 20,260,006 yen on Law No. 8, the total being 40,760,000 yen, but there was no loan caused by urgent measure. The above loans were fixed and issued by contract papers stating the amount of the loan, or by special orders delivered as necessity required. It was after the example of the tem- porary Loan Law No. 16 of February 20, 1894, which authorized borrowing from the Bank of Japan at reasonable interest to make up temporary deficits within any one fiscal year. There were two methods of obtaining the money : one by fixed loan and the other by current loan. The fixed loan is at a fixed rate of interest, the amount of the loan and terms of redemp- tion being arranged by contract paper or by command of the Minister of Finance. The current loan, on the other hand, is raised on security of money forwarded from the treasuries at different places in the Empire to the central cash office in Tokyo or the branch cash office in Osaka, the interest for the loan being the same as the daily rate for overdrafts in the Bank of Japan. The loan referred to in this paragraph was a fixed loan. The details of the loans based on Laws No. 25, 1894, and No. 8, 1895, are as follows: Loan Based on Law Xo. 25, 1894 Date of issue Amount Annual rate of interesl Hate of redemption Nov. 15, 1894 Nov. 26, 1894 Yen 8,000,000 1,500,000 3,000,000 3,000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 Per cent 5 5 5 5 5 5 Mar. 31, 1S95 Dec. io, 1894 <■ Dec. 15, 1894 Feb. 1, 1895 Feb. 6, 1895 ■• Total 20,500,000 76 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Loan Based on Law No. 8, 1895 Date of issue Amount Annual rate of interest Date of redemption Nov. 14, 1895 Yen 2,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,500,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 2,000,000 1 ,000,000 1,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 760,000 500,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,500,000 Per cent 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 Dec. 31, 1895 1 >ec. 2, 1895 Dec. t,, i8qs >• Dec. 9, 1895 " Dec. 12, 1895 » Dec. 18, 1895. . «< Dec. 25, 1895 <■ Dec. 26, 1895 " Dec. 28, 1895 Jan. 22, 1896 Mar. 31, 1896 Jan. 28, 1896 Mar. 5, 1896 " Mar. 27, 1896 << Mar. 31, 1896 "a Mar. 31, 1896 June 30, 1896 Apr. 1, 1896 Apr. 1, 1896 •1 Apr. 6, 1896 " Total 20,260,000 » Date of redemption prolonged to June 30, 1S96, by order of the Minister of Finance. As already described, the above loan for extraordinary war expenses was a temporary measure, and in accordance with the receipts of the war loan was to be redeemed gradually. Although March 31, 1895, was the date set for redemption of the 20,500,000 yen loan raised by Law No. 25 in 1894, the battle line extended, with consequent increase of outlay, so that it was quite impossible to undertake redemption as promised. Therefore, the Minister of Finance gave notice of the postponement of redemption to the Bank of Japan, naming June 30 of the same year as the date set for redemp- tion. However, by April the cash on hand in the Treasury had increased to such an extent that 3,000,000 yen of the loan was paid off, which was the first redemption of loans from the Bank of Japan. Thereafter redemption took place frequently at the convenience of the Treasury, although sometimes redemption had to be postponed, not being completed until May, 1896. SUPPLY OF WAR FUNDS 11 The loan based on Law Xo. 8 of 1895 was redeemed in May, 1896, after having been postponed frequently, like the former loan. The details of the loan follow: Date of redemption Amount of redemption Total By Law 25 By Law 8 Apr. 18, 1895 May 1, 1895 May 15, 1895 Feb. 3, 1896 Yen 3,000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 920,000 1,310,000 4,130,000 1,300,000 440,000 700,000 160,000 2,020,000 1 ,460,000 :n,:t )0,000 Yi n 3,000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 920,000 1,310,000 4,130,000 1,300,000 440.000 7' ".000 1 60,000 2,020,000 2 1. 7^0, OOO Feb. 8, 1896 Mar. 2, 1896 Mar. 26, 1896 Mar. 26, 1896 Mar. 31, 1896 Apr. 22, 1896 May 14, 1896 May 20, 1896 Total 20,500,000 20 26« non 4<),760,000 The payment of interest for the loan stood as follows: I iscal years l'.\ law No. 25 in 1894, 5', per annum By law No. 8 in 1895 per annum Total 1894 1895 1896 Total Yen 304.384 505.274 144.366 954,024 Yen 40.685 359.549 400,234 Yen 304,384 545.959 503.915 [ ,354 Employmeni 01 Indemnity The amount transferred from the sum received as indemnity from China to the fund for making up war expenses was 82,- 171,650 yen, the details being as follow-: 78 EXPENDITURES OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Items Transferred to special account for war pur- poses War and transportation expenses for fiscal year 1897-1898 fotal 82,171,650 The amount of Chinese indemnity received for the fiscal year 1895 was 74,143,054 yen for war indemnity, 44,907,449 yen as compensation for the retrocession of the Liaotung peninsula, and the sum of 93,624 yen as the profit realized by utilizing the paid-in indemnity and the marginal profit gained from the exchange rates in Japan's favor, or 119,144,177 in all. As first it was intended that the indemnity should be devoted to extension of the army and navy. But as it was necessary to bring the special accounts for the war with China to a close at the end of March, 1896, and a public loan or a loan of over 100,000,000 yen from the bank would be required to do so, it was decided to use some of the indemnity to balance the account, rather than leave the war expense to depend on public loans and perhaps greatly disturb the money market, while at the same time an idle surplus would be piling up in the Treasury. Moreover the interest on public loans had to be met. Consequently some of the in- demnity was diverted to war expenses, leaving armament expansion to future loans. The portion of indemnity used in this way was 78,957,164.89 yen, while J, 210, 000 yen was used during the tw r o fiscal years of 1897 and 1898 for repletion of war funds. PART II ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION There are two distinct points of view from which the economic effects of war may be studied. The first includes the effects upon the ordinary life of the nation, and the second the effects upon national economics and finance. This latter includes the study of the methods of securing funds for prose- cuting the war, rehabilitating old industries and starting new ones after the war, and meeting the changes which result from the fluctuation in the exchange value of money. Of these latter changes we may mention (i) the tightening of the money market caused by large bond issues; (2) the inflation of the currency due to purchase of war supplies, etc.; (3) the rise in prices caused by the war, increase in taxes, and inflation of the currency; (4) the increase or decrease in individual incomes caused by financial instability, etc., and (5) the increase in speculation due to the foregoing causes. These, then, are the general economic effects of war to be considered, and certainly the Sino-Japanese War was no ex- ception, since all of the foregoing phenomena were to be observed during and after that conflict. This fact must be noted, how (Acr, — that it was the first international war in the history of modern Japan, i.e., since the beginning of the Meiji Era. Only a quarter of a century had elapsed since great changes had taken place in our government, and tin-; quarter of a century therefore can not be considered a strictly normal period. .Main- serious financial problems were wait- in- to be solved, such as the adjustment of debts contracted during the feudal or Tokugawa epoch, the securing of money for the various needs of the new government and expenditure <»f the same, and the disposal of a large number of inconvertible notes. Moreover the new government was beset with other difficulties — the initial conflicts of the Restoration period, 7 81 82 ECONOMK EFFECTS OF NIK SINO-JAPANESE WAR the civil war of the Southwest (1877), etc. As a result, finances became constantly more difficult to manage, and when the issue of inconvertible notes finally reached the highest possible point, a decline in value set in. Only when a central bank — the Bank of Japan — had been established, was the agio, or difference in value between specie and notes, removed. In 1883 a monetary standard was established which was virtually silver, although by statute it was bi- metallic. Soon thereafter, owing to the fluctuation in value of silver and gold, monetary' complications arose, and before these had been settled the Sino-Japanese War broke out. Then, in addition to the internal problems with which we were already wrestling, we found ourselves face to face with China in the war of 1894 — China that ancient nation with the prestige of her four thousand years of history to count upon. For a nation like Japan, economically unsteady, and not yet prepared for a long fight, to challenge such an antagonist was like sweeping the sea with a broom — an impossible task, indeed, it seemed! So, although the valiant spirit of the people made up for the shortage of material supplies to some extent, we must admit that our power of continued resistance, financial and economical, was very weak, and that the effects of war upon the national economics and finance were very severe. First, let us proceed to consider the financial effects of the war. The whole expenditure amounted to more than 250,- 000,000 yen. Besides this, the expenses of various post-bellum undertakings were enormous, so that the people had to endure a constant and heavy drain. The total amount of the Treas- ury's annual disbursement at once became double that before the war. As to revenues, taxes had not been materially in- creased in order to meet the expenditure during the war, as this was largely met by means of war loans; while for restoring normal conditions after the war and for various post-bellum undertakings the war indemnity secured was employed. But this, although large, was not sufficient, and it was necessary therefore to increase the taxes and to float loans in addition. INTRODUCTION 83 In consequence, the whole nation, and economic circles in particular, became heavily burdened. Next, let us consider the general economic effects of the war. In the first place, owing to the issue of war bonds the money market was greatly tightened, but after victory was secured the conditions improved. After the war, the govern- ment and the Bank of Japan began to lend capital. By changing a virtual silver standard into a gold standard, the barrier to the free circulation of capital between Japan and the gold-standard nations was removed, and, with a view to perfecting financial facilities, hypothec and industrial banks were established. The loan power of the Bank of Japan was extended. The national banks, which so far had been an incubus upon industry, were transformed into ordinary banks. These steps facilitated the circulation of capital and helped considerably to ease the money market. But this easy condition, together with the craze for speculation rife among a people drunk with victory, caused a great financial panic which subsided only in 1 903-1 904. Secondly, as a result of issuing bonds during the war, and increasing taxes and notes as a measure of relief for the financial world, the volume of currency was considerably en- larged and the prices of commodities in general rose, the more so as the money market before the war had been tight and the entire amount of currency small. To take another point of view, let us consider that the Sino-Japanese War was the first international war which Japan had fought in modern times and that the people were unaccustomed to such experiences as they were then having. In addition, mindful of the dangers of fighting against this vast and ancient empire, they were entertaining grave anx- ieties as to the future. Fortunately for Japan, the war ended in a glorious victory for her so that the people came to realize that the efforts made during the quarter of a century past had not been made in vain. They were then fired with ambition to exert more energy along the line of national endeavor, so that Japan might extend her power in the Far East, and to 84 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR this end the government and people cooperated in various post-bellum undertakings. Means of communication and transportation, as well as financial organs, were perfected, educational institutions were improved, industries encouraged, various facilities to develop foreign trade established, and the system of encouraging shipbuilding and navigation by sub- sidies or grants of money was established. Thus the com- mercial standing of the nation was improved and industry, commerce, communication and various hitherto undeveloped enterprises were revolutionized so as to fit in with the new period, and therefore any discussion of the effects of the war is really identical with an historical statement of the progress made in these national activities. As for the increase or decrease in individual incomes, such are the inevitable results of wars and other great cataclysms of society. Especially is this true when the stock market is favorable, following the inception of post-bellum enterprises by the government and people. After the Sino-Japanese War great changes in private incomes were particularly common. The foregoing various phenomena were important results of the war. But what is to be considered as the most important result was the effect of the war upon the life of the people. This was felt for a very much longer period than other effects. The expenditure for the Sino-Japanese War was about 250 million yen. But we must also take into consideration the indirect losses suffered on account of the war, the expenditure required to restore normal conditions after the war, and the capital employed for various post-bellum undertakings. When these losses and expenses are added together, the amount reaches an enormous figure. This amount could be tempo- rarily met to be sure by means of bond issues, loans secured from the central bank, the sale of government property, and contributions by the people (especially during the war), etc. But in the long run it had to be met by revenue from taxes (direct and indirect), and the result was (1) an increase in the burdens borne by the people by the establishment of new and the increase of old taxes; (2) the permanent inflation of the INTRODUCTION 85 currency; and (3) a rise in the prices of commodities, etc. The difference between rich and poor then became more noticeable, the difficulty of living on the part of the majority of the people and also their discontent increased, while social and political transformations consequent upon the foregoing phenomena took place. These changes, indeed, constitute the most important problem for study. The increase in the burdens of the people, the inflation of the currency, and the rise in the prices of commodities were all actual phenomena observed after the Sino-Japanese War. Fortunately in Japan wages for labor and the other sources of income of the people rose in proportion to the rise in pri< so that the evil effects of the change were not felt so very sharply. But the increase in the difference between rich and poor and the difficulty of living for the majority became more and more well-defined facts, so that farmers began i<> leave their homes and flock to cities or manufacturing town-. The beauty and simplicity of country life which had generally prevailed before was gone and the country districts were left to decay. Concentration of the population in cities tended t< > increase the difficulty of living. But as Japan has only recently been opened to Western civilization, and is situated in the Far East where the civilized nations of the west are con- centrating their energy upon conquest, she has been so busily engaged in establishing herself as an independent power that she has not yet had time to pay proper attention to the question of living as it concern- the generality of the people. Consequently, the burdens of the people increased considerably after the Sino-Japanese War, and even yet they can not enjoy the happiness of perfect li\ ing conditions. Yet this state of affair- was the natural result of the geographical position of Japan, and it may not be strictly true to say that it was a direct result of the Sino-Japanese War. But .1- international diplomatic relations of Japan assumed more importance, with the Si no- Japanese War as the Starting point, and as it was this war which exposed the weakness of China and thereby encouraged the Western Tower- to bring pressure 86 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR to bear upon the East, our statement in the foregoing para- graph may be seen to be a correct one. We shall now go into more detail as to each of the phenomena mentioned above, expressing our views in concrete form in order to show how far reaching the effect of the Sino-Japanese War was upon our economic world. CHAPTER II EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE The effects of the Sirio-Japanese War on public finance were most directly shown in the annual budgets of the government. We shall therefore present tables giving the annual budgets from 1893, the year before the Sino-Japanese War, t< 1 [903, the year before the Russo-Japanese War, in order to show the influ- ence of the former war upon the annual budgets of the nation. Annual Revenue, 1893-1903 Fiscal Year Ordinary Extraordinary 1893 i894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Total Yen 85,883,080 89,748,454 95,444,652 104,904,501 124,222,964 132,869,336 192,170,081 202,035,100 221.240,408 224,180,699 Yen 27,886,300 8,421,574 22,988,069 82,114,022 102,167,159 87,184,792 76,925,996 103,684,787 72,323,950 76,101,016 10,059 650,027,803 : \wi m. Expenditures, 1893-1903 Fiscal 1893 1895 1896 1897. 1898. 1899. 1900 1 901 . 1902. 1903 Total. < Irdinary Yen '■4.545.599 60,421,346 '■7.1 |.8,007 [00,7I2,8l6 [07,695,127 1 19,072.144 1 $7,590,418 1 iw.i.vi.i": [60,363,583 171,05 169,761,91 1 307.5" Extraordinary Yen 20,036,273 I7.7<>7. 2 97 18,169,173 68,3 ; 1 [5.983.717 100,(1*5,42 i 1 16,575,120 [43,615,892 106,493,241 1 18, K>(i. <,J3 14.217 Total Vtii 1 1 $,769,380 98,170,028 118,452.721 187.oiw.125 226,390.125 220,054,128 254,254,524 295,854,868 274.359.050 297,341,424 260,220 758 Total Yen 84.581,872 78,128,643 85,317,180 168,856,508 223,678,844 219.757.568 254,165,538 292,75 26,731 249.596,131 1. 2 1 2, (j 1 5.898 87 8S ECONOMIC II I 1 .< TS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Taking the figures for 1893 as 100, the percentages of the figures for the other years will be as follows: Annual Revenue and Expenditures, 1893-1903, in Percentage 1 is al j ear 1893 1894 1895 !*(,(, 1897 I898 I899 I900 I90I I902 1903 k<-\ enue 1 >rdinary 100. o 104.5 1 r 1 . 1 122 144 154 206 223 235 257 261 Extraor- dinary 100. o 30.2 82.4 294 5 366.4 312.6 275-9 371 8 259 -4 272.9 129.2 Total 100. o 86.3 104. 1 164.4 199.0 193-4 223.5 260. 1 241 .2 261 .4 228.7 Expendit ures Ordinary 1 00.0 93-6 104.0 156.0 166.9 184.4 213. 1 231 .1 248.5 265.0 263.0 Extraor- dinary 90. 34° ■ 578. 502 58l 716. 531 589- 398. Total 100. 4 92. 7 100. 1 199. 9 283 5 259 8 300 8 346 5 315 8 342 4 295 The foregoing tables show that the annual budget which was 84 million yen in 1897 became twice as big after the war, that is, over 168 million yen. It increased gradually until in 1903 it reached over 249 million yen, that is, an increase of 195 per cent. Now what was the cause of this increase in ex- penditure, and from what source was the revenue to come to offset it? To make this clear will be to make clear the effects of the war upon finance. The Sino-Japanese War was, as stated above, the first in- ternational war which Japan had waged since the Restoration of Meiji. Abroad it raised the status of Japan and proved her to be in reality the protector of the safety and peace of the Far East, and thus gave her an established position among the great powers of the world. At home, it enabled her to realize her own power, through the experience of a continental war, and at the same time gave her the opportunity to rise in power, through victory in this war, in accordance with the forward policy laid down at the time of the Restoration. Even the tragic incident at the close of this war, the interference by the three European Powers, was only an added incentive to the EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FIXAN< I 89 nation to exert her utmost energy for the development of national power and the replenishment and expansion of the provisions for national defense. Naturally the expenditures greatly increased, because an enormous amount of money was needed at the time of the war, not only for war expenses hut also for the increase in the ordinary administrative expenses owing to the war, and again after the war to repay the princi- pal and interest of the various war bonds. These were assuredly the reasons why the annual national budget in- creased so much after the Sino-Japanese War. The effects of the war upon national finance may be dis- cussed under two headings — (1) Securing of a war fund and readjustments incident thereto. (2) Post-bellum enterprises. The first of these two points was discussed in detail in the third Chapter of Part I, under the heading "Supply of War Funds," so we shall omit it here. We might remark here, however, that the only item under this head which caused financial trouble in later days was the issue of war bond-. 1 The redemption and interest payments on these bonds were completed in July, 1910. We shall discuss this matter in detail in the next section. As for the enterprises undertaken after the war, they were many and various. The chief items were (I) rehabilitation and expansion of the army and the navy f the latter on a scale commensurate with the change in the national status after the war) and the establishment of an iron foundry; (2) im- provement of educational institutions in order to cherish and develop the national strength, increase of legations abroad, river repairs, railway construction and improvement, exten- sion of the telephone system, expansion of foreign trade, subsidies for shipbuilding, encouragement of navigation and extension of sea traffic, readjustment of the monetary system, perfecting of financial facilities and agricultural institutions, 1 Amount of bonds issued, 124,920,750 yen; amount actually received, [22,437,- 687 yen. 90 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR colonial development of Hokkaido, and the establishment of various facilities for the government of the newly acquired territories. In order to put the foregoing plans into execution, the government approved the national budget outlined below: 1. Plan to meet the increase in expenditure after 1896: (a) As sources of revenue to meet ordinary expenditure due to post-bellum undertakings, a sake tax, a business tax, and a registry tax shall be levied, and a leaf tobacco monopoly established. (b) For army and navy expansion and for the establishment of a new iron foundry, a part of the indemnity collected from China was to be used. (c) As sources of revenue for railway and telephone im- provement or extension, bonds were to be issued. 2. Plan to meet the war expenditure, dispose of the in- demnity received from China and provide a budget system for Formosa: (a) As the indemnity was collected from China in yearly instalments, it seemed wise to appropriate the money for use in a continuation plan embracing a certain number of years. Thus the indemnity was appropriated for the redemption of war debts, army and navy expansion, the establishment of an iron foundry, a reserve fund for emergencies and a subsidy to the Bank of Agriculture and Industry. (b) The annual budget for Formosa was to be separated from the general accounts of the central government and a plan worked out relative to annual revenue and expenditure which should be instituted to enable Formosa gradually to establish a system of self-government. 3. Plan to extend facilities for transportation, communica- tion and finance: (a) Bonds were to be issued to meet the expense of im- provement and extension of railways and telephones. (b) The service capacity of the Bank of Japan and the Yokohama Specie Bank were to be enlarged and in addition a hypothec bank and banks of agriculture and industry were to be established. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 91 We shall now briefly consider the amount required and the resources available for the fund to earn,- out the proposed plans, including the extension of the means of national de- fense, the perfection of railway and telephone systems, the establishment of a new iron foundry, and especially the encouragement of navigation. Table I at the end of this chapter 1 and the following tables will give a fair idea of the effects of the Sino-Japanese War upon our national finance as a whole. Comparing the total amounts in Table I 1 with the total annual expenditure, we see that in ten years these amounts actually correspond (in average) to approximately 28.29 per cent of the total annual expenditure. Comparison of Expenditures for Post-bellum Enterprises with the Total Annual Expenditures Fiscal year Total expenditure for principal post- bellum enterprises Total annual expenditures Percentage of post- bellum expenses to total annual ex- penditures 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 Yen 2,827,)'.; 5,279,892 29,303,746 85,048,595 94,813,702 112,062,975 118,639,050 98,278,837 75,965,524 67,i37.5 Yen 78,128,643 85,3i7.i7'» 168,856,509 223,678,844 2i9.757.569 254,165,528 292,750,059 266,856, 82 \ 289,226,731 249,5.)'.. 1 p Per cent 3.62 6.19 17-35 38.02 43 M 44.09 40.53 36.83 26. 27 26 90 1899 1 900 1901 1902 1903 Total 689,356,7 s '' 2,128,334,017 28.29* ' Av. I In order to secure t His large amount, the government, as stated before, adopted the measures of increasing taxes, issuing bonds and transferring the war indemnity. The following table will show the most important items of revenue: 8 1 Post, p. 141. 2 The figures for the revenue from ne\vl\ established taxes were taken from the actual receipts and the figures for the old taxes whos< rates were raised were taken from the estimate of the expe< ted incn The revenue from the bond issues me. ms the revenue from the bonds issued for the railways, the industries, the Hokkaido railways and the Formosan enterpi 92 ECONOMK I I M< IS OF THE SINO-JAPANESH WAR Revenue foh Post-bellum Enterprises I iscal year Kc\ enue from increase oi taxes Transfer of indemnity fund Issue of bonds Total 1896 ' 897 [898 [899 1900 1 90 1 1902 1903 Yen i,s,7<>8.589 29,701,472 35.6i7,ioo 63,810,962 85,710,491 90, 104,052 95.621,115 100,073 693 Yen 11,789,389 40,360,796 46,187,071 32,636,905 31,240,140 20,883,427 13.866,937 9,514.215 Yen 2,796,600 36,389.8/4 35,352,806 35,166,404 38,139.599 31.721,764 12,741,033 6,881,256 Yen 30,294,578 106,452,142 H7,i56,977 131,614,271 155090,230 143,009,243 122,229,085 1 16,469,164 Total . . . 516,647,474 206 478,880 199,189,336 922,315,690 With the expansion of the general national finance owing to the aforesaid causes, the expenditure of the local governments naturally increased in proportion. Table II at the end of this chapter 1 was taken from the report of the investigation of the Home Department to show the actual condition as to expansion of revenue and expenditure of local communities. The cause of this increase in expenditure was largely due to the increase required for construction work, encouragement of industry and educational enterprises, because of the policy adopted by local communities to develop the national re- sources and industries in accordance with the post-bellum plans of expansion. According to the Japanese system of government, the local communities (prefecture, city, borough, township, village) have been invested with complete power as legal persons, and the officials in these local communities, besides performing their duties to the communities, are called upon for the additional service of managing the various local enterprises entrusted to them by the central government and of supervising the expenditure therefor. With a change in the status of the nation the duties of these local officials were correspondingly increased, and hence the increase in local expenditure. Thus, since the expansion of the finance of local governments inevitably keeps pace with the advance- 1 Post, p. 142. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 93 merit of a nation, it was natural that with the national expansion along various lines after the Sino-Japanese War, an increase in local expenditure should take place also. In short, after the Sino-Japanese War, Japan spent enor- mous amounts for central and local administration in view of the post-bellum enterprises, that is, for expansion of means of defense, development of resources and industries, and for improvement of education. The pressure of this increase of expenditure upon the people was certainly crushing. This together with the changes caused by the war upon economics in general produced serious effects upon the economic world, which lasted throughout the entire period in which the post- bellum enterprises were being prosecuted, as we state more fully later. But, on the other hand, our fellow countrymen, moved by the new self-realization following the war, and by the feeling of uncertainty concerning the national existence due to the insult inflicted upon us by the interference of the triple European Powers, rose to the occasion, and sturdily resisted the paralyzing pressure of circumstances. We have successfully prosecuted the post-bellum enterprises started by the government, mastered all difficulties by developing the power of resistance, and Anally raised the nation's prestige so high that within the short period of ten years or so Japan has risen to be a mighty power in her recently enlarged sphere in the Far East. This fact should be remembered in discuss- ing the financial expansion of the nation. This indomitable spirit asserted itself more and more so that Japan did not retrograde in any direction. This is the reason win- we have peace in the Orient, a fact which should be recorded as in the nature of a miracle. State Finance We have briefly reviewed the effects of the Sino-Japanese War upon the national finance in general. To sum up. the expenditure in the first year alter the war, [896, was twice as large as that for the year before the war, [893, and three years after, in [899, it was three times as large. This tendency 94 I < ONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR to increase continued steadily until the year 1903 just before the Russo-Japanese War. Such was the history of the expenditure. As for the revenue, in 1897 it was twice as large as in 1893, and the tendency to increase continued. In 1893 the revenue was 113,769*380.54 yen and the expenditure 84,581,871.56 yew; that is, there was an excess of 29,187,508.97 yen of revenue over expenditure, so that the rate of expansion of the revenue in later years was not so extraordinary as that of the expenditure. Table III at the end of this chapter 1 was compiled to show these facts. The direct effects of the Sino-Japanese War upon our finance were felt in securing special administration funds for the war and in connection with the war (hereafter called war expenses). The total amount of these expenses was approximately 236 million yen. The greater part of this amount was secured through the issue of war bonds and the transfer of the war indemnity, so that it did not have any very serious effect upon the ordinary revenue of the nation, as we have stated before. 2 Consequently the burden of the war expenses which had to be borne afterward was confined to the redemption of the war bonds and the payment of interest on them. We shall later explain this point in detail. Thus it will be seen that the greatest effects of the Sino- Japanese War upon our finance were in connection with post- bellum enterprises. Of those undertaken since 1896, the chief, as stated before, were the enlargement of the army and navy, the establishment of an iron foundry, the building and improvement of railways, the extension of the telephone system, the extension of educational work, the establishment of the Hypothec Bank, the Banks of Agriculture and Industry and the Bank of Formosa, enterprises in Formosa, undertak- ings in agriculture, industry and commerce and the adjust- ment of water courses. All these enterprises had for their object the perfecting of the means of national defense and the developing of the wealth of the nation. We shall here briefly describe the plans for these post-bellum enterprises. 1 Post, p.m. ■ Pt. I, Chap. ill. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINAN< I 95 (1) According to the documents introduced in the Diet, together with the budget in 1896, the post-bellum enterprises were planned to be completed in ten years, from 1896 to 1905, with the amount of expenditure estimated at about 587 million yen; the tax system was readjusted, a part of the war indemnity was to be transferred to the fund and bonds were to be issued to meet the remainder. The following is the total expenditure for the ten years. ... . . Total Expenditure fob Period 1896-1905 Expansion of means of defense: Yen Yen Army 205,802,866 Nav y 145,572,264 ~ _ . , . 351.375.130 Extension ot enterprises: Iron foundry 4.095.793 Railway to be built between Sorachita and Asahig- awa i,i 78,330 Improvement of existing government railway lines 26,553,000 Extension of telephone exchange system 12,802,102 I irsl year's interest on telephone and railway bonds 1,278,080 Establishment of bureaus to handle leaf tobacco and capital 12,213,550 ... 58,120,855 Expansion ol administrative expenditure: Principal and interest payments on loans 1 10,401,056 Annual salaries of soldiers, rewards and pensions. . . 1 12,940,810 Expense of collecting increased taxes I2 >653.833 Expenses of soldiers stationed in Weihaiwei and various Formosan expenses 27,500,000 Subsidies to banks 13,750,000 Expenses of printing and issuing bonds 598,520 277.844.Jiw Total 687.340,204 The complete ten-year plan for revenue t<> meet the Ion- going items of expenditure is as follows: rEN-YEAF Rj \ INI B PLAN, 1896 [905 Yen Natural increase of annual revenue 147,698,97] Increased taxes and adjustment <>i ia\ system 2 j<>.- Fund to pay off the expenses of guards at Weihaiwei War indemnity 40,093, $87 '* on ' is ■ • 133.048,889 Profits from bonds for railway and telephone enterpi ises 1 1 ,680,4 '4 Total 584.914.742 ()(> ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR 2 I The plans for post-bellum enterprises did not end with those mentioned in the foregoing paragraphs. Both the number of enterprises and the amount of appropriation asked for were increased. In the enlarged scheme the principal items were means of defense, construction of railways and establishment of an iron foundry. The change in the plan relating to expenditure necessitated a change in the plan for securing revenue. The taxes were increased again, the amount transferred from the war indemnity was also increased and the bond issue enlarged, thereby maintaining the balance between expenditure and revenue. This point will be explained in detail later. There is one more point to be noted here, and that is re- garding the revenue from the indemnity of the Sino-Japanese War. The total amount of the indemnity and other special funds was 368,248,691 yen. The war indemnity and other revenues were handled as a "Special Account Fund" in accordance with our accounting regulations. These separate amounts are shown as follows : Yen Yen Indemnity for war expenses 311,072,865 Indemnity for return of Liaotung Peninsula 44,907,499 Interest on indemnity employed profitably 8,888,224 ■ ■ 364,868,588 Fund to pay back expense of maintaining guards at Weihaiwei 3,380,103 Total 368,248,691 The indemnity as analyzed in the foregoing paragraph was an adequate source of revenue for conducting post-bellum enterprises and replenishing the war fund. The total amount actually transferred for the support of post-bellum enterprises was 278,690,217 yen. The details are as follows: Yen Repayment of Sino-Japanese War expenses 78,957,165 Transferred to fund for various post-bellum enterprises: Yen Army expansion 56,781 .709 \,i\ \ expansion . 139,157,096 1 stablishment of iron foundry 579,762 Fund for special war expenses, transportation, communication, 1897 3,214,485 I99-733-053 Total 278,690,217 EFFECTS OX PUBLU FINANCE 97 The foregoing amounts were drawn from the 364,868,587 of indemnity. The fund to pay back the expense of maintaining guards at Weihaiwei was from the beginning transferred from the general account. Of the indemnity received, 20 million yen was transferred to a fund for the use of the Im- perial family, 50 million yen to three funds, viz.. one for replenishing warships and torpedo boats, another for emer- gencies due to natural disasters and the third for educational purposes, while 12 million yen was transferred to the General Account in 1898. The greater part of the indemnity and the special revenues was used for the war and for various other expenses connected with the war. The indemnity has had a considerable effect upon our national finance. We shall discuss it in detail later. Expansion of means of defense The government recognized, after the war with China, that the then existing army and navy were inadequate, in view of the condition of the country at that period, and formulated a plan of expansion which was put into execution from 1895. For the first period of expansion, the army asked for an appropriation of 43,320,000 yen as a fund for a continuation plan to extend over four years, from 1895 until 1899, and the navv asked for (4. 770.000 yen as a fund for a similar plan covering the seven years from 1895 until 1903. The general outline of these plans of expansion was for the army t< tablish additional divisions and to construct fortresses, etc., and for the navy to increase it- strength by means of new warships and torpedoes. Up to that period our military strength was seven divisions for standing service, with about 50,000 men in time of peace and 200,000 iu time of war. According to the new plan >ix new divisions were to be added. so that in peace the number of men would be 150,000 and in war about 600.000. And the navy which had up to that period 50,000 tons of warships, was to be increased to 200,000 tons or more. The new plans of expansion were severely criticised by the people. 98 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR There was much opposition in the national Diet. But the nation generally recognized the need of expansion of the means of defense, and the plans were at length carried out. But in the first period of expansion, the army counted only the cost of erecting fortresses, building barracks, securing the first supply of arms and implements for use in camp and other immediately necessary expenses for the standing army. The arrangements necessary for war preparedness had not yet been perfected. The navy counted only the cost of the number of warships and torpedoes which were immediately needed, and in order to perfect the original plan still larger appropriations had to be asked for. Thorough investigation was therefore made as to the unfinished work after that, and, as a result, additional appropriations were asked for in the budget for 1897. The estimate of expenses for the second period of expan- sion was 38,350,000 yen for the army as a fund for the contin- uation plan from 1897 to 1903; and 118,320,000 yen for the navy for a similar plan from 1897 to 1905; totaling 156,670,- 000 yen for both army and navy. These demands of the army and navy were secured through the approval of the Diet. In 1899 the third period of expansion was entered upon in accordance with the plans described in the foregoing para- graphs. The establishment of the seven army divisions was perfected and fortresses were improved or newly made in the islands of Formosa and Pescadores. For all of these 18,040,000 yen was requested, as a fund for a continuation plan extending from 1899 to 1906. Besides the foregoing, in the same year, the appropriation for army expansion had to be increased owing to the rise in prices, so that an additional 5,210,000 yen was appropriated as a fund for repairs, for securing implements and for the mis- cellaneous expenses of the construction bureau, while the naval expansion fund was reduced by 1,450,000 yen after providing for construction of the fortresses already decided upon, owing to a difference in the exchange rates of 3,350,000 yen. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 99 Thus the plans for expansion of the army and navy were commenced in 1896 and after going through the first and the second period of expansion were nearly completed when in 1899 the plans for the establishment of the seventh division, and construction of the fortresses in Tsushima, Kielung and Pescadores Island, were carried out, so that great financial problems of the past four years were solved for the time being. Just how great was the expenditure for defense after th< great plans for expansion had been laid, is shown in the foll< >\v- ing tables: Expenditures for Defense, 1 893-1903 A r»i v Fiscal year Ordinary Extraordinary Total 1893 Yen 12,419,829 7,828,074 8,410,212 22,613,590 28,746,263 32,562,072 35,577.3io 36,123,892 37,433.9" 39,169,669 39.355.388 Yen 2,301,397 2,580,862 1,605,723 30,628,934 31,401,725 2i.335-58i 16,973,888 38,714,309 20,947,869 10,272,390 7.529. '74 Yen 14,721,226 1 894 10,408,936 10,01 5 53,242.524 60,147,988 1895 1896 1897 1898 53.897.< : 52,551,] 74,838,201 1899 1900 1 901 58,381,7 49,442 ,< ■ 1 902 iqoi 46,884,562 Total 300,240,210 184,291,852 484,532,062 Navy Fiscal year ( Ordinary Extraordinary Total 1 893 Yen 5. 1 4 1. 475 4,573.605 4,913,244 7.35L330 9.54 1 1. km. 475 I4.577.li4 [6,91 1,000 19.484.953 21,063,345 21,530,237 Yen 1,549 8,607 12,1 ; . 40,850,645 47.338,427 47,084,496 41,363 I 24.494,375 14.587,620 ) \ n 8,100,921 [894 [895 1 896 10,253,154 [3,520,269 1898 1899 1900 02 61 ,66i ,6io 58,274,895 1901 1902 43,979,3 $26,188 36,117,857 1 903 Total 136,281 .667 749 397,164,416 [00 ECONOMIC Mil' rS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE AVAR From this table it will be seen that after 1896 both the ordinary and the extraordinary expenditures suddenly in- creased. The amount of increase required by the plan of expansion of the means of defense may be seen from the follow- ing, abstracted from the figures in the foregoing table: 1 Increased Expenditures for Army and Navy, Due to Plan of Expansion, 1 896-1 903 Army Navy Total for Fiscal year Ordinary Extraor- dinary Total Extraor- dinary Army and Navy 1896. . . . 1897- ... 1898 1899. ... 1900. . . . 1901 1902. . . . 1903 Yen 4,548,454 4.981,063 8,675,720 12,423.570 13.171,994 i3,U5.759 13,149,013 I3,423.344 Yen 8,437,262 21,914,002 14.847,021 14,055,883 19,202,826 11,669,525 6,192,555 4,628,109 Yen 12,985,716 26,895,065 23,522.741 26,479,453 32,374,820 24,815,284 19.341,568 18,051,453 Yen 4.043,288 32,487,404 44,554,683 45,369,046 33,238,685 21,147,756 12,568,445 9,552,430 Yen 17,029,004 59.382,469 68,077,424 71,848,499 65,613,505 45,963,040 31,910,013 27,603,883 Total . 83,518,917 100,947,183 184.466,100 202,961,737 387,427,837 We have briefly explained the tendency to an increase in both ordinary and extraordinary expenses in accordance with the plan of expansion of the army and the navy. We must now proceed to explain in detail the extraordinary expenditure which is the main thing in the plan of expansion of the means of defense. As we have before stated, this plan was carried out gradually, having been incorporated in the budget of 1896 as the first period, in 1897 as the second, and in 1899 as the third, thereby gradually perfecting the work of national de- fense as a part of the post-bellum program. The following is a table of the amounts required by this expansion plan: 1 The ordinary expenditure for the army includes the expenses of the seventh, eighth, ninth, tenth, eleventh and twelfth divisions, the expenses of the guards in Formosa and other miscellaneous expenses, the expenses of the guards in Korea and the expenses of the guards at \\ eihaiwei. Of these, the last two items have no relation to the plan of expansion of defenses. But as they are the result of the war, they are included in the figures here given. As for the ordinary expenditure for the navy, as it is difficult to single out the expenses due to the plan of expansion, they are not given here separately. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINAN< I. IOI Budget of Extraordinary Expenses Due to Expansion Plan First period, 1896 on Second period, 1897 on Third period, 1899 on Additional appropria- tion, 1899 Total Army: Construction of fortresses. Repairs and initial pur- Yen 14,071.894 17.334.891 8,486,767 2,949,108 479.376 Yen 6,460,520 19.363.747 9.854.338 3.542 2,679,790 Yen ' 9.829,134 8,220,583 Yen 5,208,478 Yen 27,010,197* 7.699 18,341.30s 2,949,108 118 j. 790 Expansion of plant in Expenses of Army Con- Deficit Total 43.322,236 38,362,137 18,049,717 5,208.478 •I.2I7 b Navy: Ship construction Manufacture of arms Construction expenses. . . . 47. 154. 576 33.75I.l63 13.870,507 78,893.399 33,176,330 6.25 125,169,547° 66,35 - 5.497 Total 94,776,246 118,324,719 138,098,482 156.686.855 18,049,717 5.208.478 3l3.24l.333 b » The difference in exchange rate, 3.35I.35I yen, has been deducted. b The difference in exchange rate has been deducted. c The difference in exchange rate, 572.421 yen, has been deducted. d The difference in exchange rate. 878,428 yen, has been deducted. The results of the execution of the foregoing budget may be seen in the following tabic: Extraordinary Expansion Expi Army Repairs and Fiscal year Construction initial pur- Manufacture of fori ; chase of of arms Additional Total arms Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen 1,291,730 5.739,279 934.o6i 472,192 17,262 1897 3,157,624 [2,601 ,55 s 19,205 5.515.1.15 21 ,914,002 1898 2,970, I'M 7,4<>4.5PO 2,492,243 [,97 1 tf,021 1899 3.465.359 6,928,578 3.541.755 1 20, 1 9 2 I4,< 1900 5,616,9] 2 9.309.375 4,216,945 59 - [9,21 1901 4.433.293 4.482,973 2,706,436 46 • [i,6 1902 1,591,202 2,756,393 I .M 0,659 44 I 6,2< 1903 2,919,341 [,697,81 1 10,957 4,62 Total . 25,445,862 (0,467 [8,341,304 6,249,551 100,957,184 102 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Navy Fiscal year Construction of ships Manufacture of arms Construction of buildings Total 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Yen 3,099,482 23,913-987 30,298,987 26,233,569 17,565,610 9,523,391 5,964,095 4,826,199 Yen 799,209 7,218,321 12,440,942 16,859,198 12,498,883 7,382,769 3.829,959 2,592,492 Yen 144,596 1,355,096 1,814,753 2,276,279. 3,174.192 4,241,596 2,774,391 2,134,739 Yen 4,043,287 32,487,404 44,554,682 45,369.046 33,238,685 21,147,756 12,568,445 9.553,430 Total. . . . 121,425,320 63,621,773 17,915,642 202,962735 Li crease oj administrative expenses Not only did the administrative expenses of various kinds increase on account of the plans for the post-bellum enter- prises after the Sino-Japanese War but by reason of the general national advancement, which added to the increase in administrative expenses. The following table shows the expense of the public debts, the expenditure for defense and the general administrative expenses separately: Expenditures on Account of Public Debts, Defense, and Administration Fiscal year Public Debts Defenses General Ad- ministration Total Yen Yen Yen Yen 1893 19,455,918 22,905,993 43,457,517 85,819,428 1894 19,721,143 20,764,267 40,304,766 80,790,176 1895 24,190,858 23,671,985 39.580,507 87,443,350 1896 30,504,172 73,416,902 68,479,552 172,400,626 1897 29,504,731 110,666,757 91,459,859 231,631,347 1898 28,379,828 112,634,626 85,990,576 227,005,030 1899 34,278,956 114,307,693 105,578,889 254,165,538 1900 34.841.135 I33.i73,58i 124,735,343 292,750,059 1901 38,085,910 102,248,927 126,521,988 266,856,825 1902 76,075,690 85,863,957 127,287,083 289,226,730 1903 36,484,520 83,2 1 ^ 02 6 129,893.585 249,596,131 Total.. . . 371,522,861 882,872,714 983,289,665 2,237,685,240 The following table shows the foregoing different items of expense in their respective ratios, and how large was the ratio of the general administrative expense. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC IT NAN' I 103 Ratio of Public Debt, Defense and Administrative Expenditures Fis tl year 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Public debts 2 2 24 27 17 u 12 13 1 1 14 26 14 I >efenses Per cent 26.7 25- 27 42 47 49 45 45 38 29 33 ( .incral Administration 7 29 1 45 6 39 8 39 6 57 4i 5 42 3 47 7 44 3 52 Per d at 50.6 9 3 7 5 9 5 6 4 o o It will be seen from Table IV at the end of this chapter 1 that the various national expenses have increased enormously since 1896. We must here briefly survey the various post- bellum enterprises which were the cause of the increase in the general administrative expenses. Of these, the following may be especially mentioned: (1) establishment of an iron foundry and extension of the same; (2) construction and improvement of railways; (3) extension of telephone ex- changes; (4) subsidies to various special banks; (5) subsidies for the encouragement of navigation; (6) sundry expenses in- curred for Formosa, etc. These will be explained in the order above enumerated. ESTABLISHMENT AND EXTENSION <>I [RON FOUNDRY The establishment of an iron foundry was the most impor- tant of the post-bellum enterprises, because the demand for iron manufactures increased enormously every year. Then in connection with the plan to extend the mean- for national de- fense it was plain that, as iron was the principal material used in building warships and manufacturing arms, in case oi emergency the supplies must be obtainable at home. Thus the iron foundry came to be established. As to the expense of its establishment, 4,095,793 yen were asked for in the national budget in 1896, and later, in [898, 6,474,056 yen more were 1 Post, p. 144. K>4 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SIXO-JAPANESE WAR added, so that the entire expense amounted to 10,569,849 yen. The work of establishing the iron foundry gradually pro- gressed, and in 1899 experiments in manufacturing from iron were being made, so that there was urgent need of securing a fixed sum as operating capital in order to commence work. The enterprise of the iron foundry is a great industry with far-reaching effects. The necessary supplies of ore, coal, cement and other materials can not be secured in sufficient amount from a few private mining concerns. Then, again, considered from the economic point of view, as it is more advantageous for an iron foundry to own its own mines, it appeared necessary to secure a fund for purchasing mines from which to obtain raw material. To hasten the work of constructing the harbor at Wakamatsu to secure transporta- tion conveniences, suitable subsidies must be given to the Wakamatsu Harbor Construction Company. In order to secure perfect results from the work of the iron foundry, the appropriation for expenses must be reasonably increased. So, in 1899, 8,632,845 yen 1 were added, the total amount finally reaching 19,202,694 yen. To meet this expense, 579,762 yen were raised from in- demnity and 18,622,932 yen from bonds. The result of the plan is seen in the following table: Fiscal year 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1 901 1 902 1903 Total. Establishment of iron foundry Yen 157,529 709,224 L747.572 3,011,008 7,126,198 5.853.335 490,117 820,011 19.914.994 Supplementary appropriation Yen 322 495 20 762 429 454 838,645 Investigation Yen 17.942 17.942 Total Yen 157,529 709,224 L747.572 3,011,008 7,126,198 6,176,097 1.003,488 840,465 20,771.581 ^00,000 yen wore for harbor construction at Wakamatsu, and 4,000,000 yen a reserve to be used as operating capital. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINAN< 1 IO5 CONSTRUCTION' AND [MPROVEMENT OF RAILWAYS 1 The new railway system was inaugurated by the Railway Construction Act promulgated June 20, 1892. The continua- tion plan adopted was to include a period of sixteen years, beginning with 1893. At the time of the Sino-Japanese War the total amount of the expense of railway construction it- required by this continuation plan reached 59,921,663 yen. Thus the work of railway construction steadily progressed and the railway lines were extended. But, at the same time, the business of transportation increased year by year, and the demand for service on the already constructed lines increased more and more, so that the existing lines and the number of cars in use were not sufficient to meet the demand. Moreover, under abnormal conditions, service had to be refused to the general public, as for instance, in time of war. So the govern- ment, as the first step in advance, changed the whole ot the Tokaido Government Railway from a single to a double- track line. Necessary improvements were added to the stations on this, and also on the Shin-Yetsu line, the number of cars was increased, and it was generally planned to give entire satisfaction to both passengers and shippers in the way of transportation facilities. This scheme was established as a continuation plan to be worked between 1896 and 1 beginning in 1896. The entire expense for improvement was estimated at 26,553,000 yen. The work of railway construction steadily progressed in accordance with the plan outlined in the foregoing paragraph. In [897 there was need of an increase in the fund tor c<>n- struction expenses between Tsuruga and Toyama.and between llachioji and Nagoya. Thus, in that year 8,103,381 yen were added, and in 1899 the fund tor construction expenses between Tsuruga and Toyama and between Sinonoi and Shiojiri was increased by 5,133,28] yen, bringing the total amount up to 73. 1 58,325 yen. Then, in [900, [9,529,886 yen were added in connection with the construction ot" the line between Fuku- 1 See Table Y at the end of this chapter, post, p. 1 +5. 106 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR shima and Aomori, and also 2,156,248 yen as construction expense for the line between Kaidaichi and Kure,so that at the end of 1900 the cost of constructing railways during the first period had reached 94,844,459 yen, and the additions made to the first estimates for construction after the war amounted to 61,475.796 yen. Besides the foregoing, in 1897 a plan for railway construc- tion in Hokkaido was formulated, involving an expenditure of 18,562,050 yen and another in 1900 for Formosa with an ex- penditure of 28,800,000 yen. We shall explain this plan later. The totals in Table V at the end of this chapter 1 show the actual results of this improvement and construction work all over the country. The funds for these railway undertakings were mostly secured by the issue of bonds. To be more specific, as shown in the table, about 77 per cent of the fund was obtained from bond issues and the rest was from the ordinary annual revenue. EXTENSION OF TELEPHONE EXCHANGES Since the telephone exchange service was commenced between Tokyo and Yokohama in 1890, and between Osaka and Kobe in 1892, the applications for telephone installation have increased year by year, so that even the present develop- ment of the system is not equal to the demand. As there were many other cities besides the four mentioned above which demanded service, after the war the government planned to establish a telephone system in Kyoto and the thirty-five other cities which needed it most urgently; then the single-line system already established was changed to a double-line system. Other extensions were planned. In 1896 the so-called continuation plan was instituted to be carried out between 1896 and 1902 with the sum of 12,802,- 107 yen appropriated for the entire cost of the extension. Furthermore, in order to increase the telegraphic lines the government executed a continuation plan between 1897 and 1898 with a budgetary estimate of 705,338.90 yen. l Post, p. 145. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 107 The following tabic shows the annual disbursement for telephone exchange extension, the actual result of the ex- tension, and the sources from which the fund was derived: Disbursements and Revenue for Teli phone Exi hange Extension Fiscal year Cost Sources of ordi- nary annual revenue Bonds issued Total revenue 1896 1897 1898 1899 1 900 1 901 1902 1903 594,196 2,473.420 1,896,1 19 1,781,655 2,349,786 1,807,587 I. ''1 5.532 268,556 Yen 437. < s 75 72,790 Yen 594,196 2,473,420 1 ,89(1,1 19 1,781,655 2.34" 1,807,587 1,177.657 195.766 Yen 594.196 N.420 1 ,896,1 19 [,781 2,349 1,807 1,615,532 268,556 Total .... t2.786.851 510,665 12,276,186 12,786,851 SUBSIDIES TO VARIOUS SPECIAL BANKS Another method adopted to improve financial facilities after the Sino-Japanese War was the granting of subsidies to various banks, as tabulated below. Fiscal year Hypothec Bank Agricultural and Indus- trial Bank I [okkaido ( lolonial Bank Formosa Colonial Bank Industrial Bank of Japan Total 1897... 1898.. . 1 899. . . 1900. . . 1901. . . 1902. . . 1903- • Yen 55,052 30,010 30,873 Yen 991,625 1,983.355 1,990,008 1,996,010 940,224 213,901 5,000 Yen 250,000 250,000 200,000 200,000 Yen 250,000 . ^0,000 6 Yen +.541 1.046,677 2,013,365 2.520,881 jfi.OIO [,140,22 \ 728,442 5.000 Total "5,935 8,120,123 1111(1,000 5< 10,000 64,54' 9,700,599 EN( nt K \«,| \tl\i OF NAVIGA1 ION Special encouragement to navigation was early planned in accordance with the proclamation issued in September, 1886. The government thereupon subsidized the Nippon Yusen Kaisha to the extent of 880,000 yen annually, thus enabling 108 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR that company to institute regular sendee between Yokohama .iihI Shanghai, Kobe and Tientsin, Kobe and Neuchang, Kobe and Vladivostok, between various other points in Japan proper and Hokkaido and various points along the line. But the period of effectiveness of the proclamation expired in September, 1900, and it then became necessary to estab- lish a policy to govern the regular service in the future. Previous to that, in 1896, with the object of encouraging navigation, the government had promulgated a law according to which subsidiary grants would be made to ships which should subscribe to certain requirements. The highest amount designated for this purpose was one million yen annually, but the actual result of the operation of this law was such an increase in ships that in 1897 no less sum than 1,700,000 yen was required for this purpose, while in 1898 the amount needed for subsidies and extension of steamship routes ran above five million yen. Now after the term of subsidy to the Nippon Yusen Kaisha had expired, it was found that if the general law were to be applied to the com- pany in the future as it had been in the past the expense would be increased enormously. So discussion centered about the point whether the general regulations should be applied to the leading regular service routes, or new special regulations should be established. The government decided upon the latter course, and introduced into the Diet a bill which was later approved empowering the government to sign a contract for an annual subsidy of 580,000 yen for five years, from October, 1900, to September, 1905, for the chief regular connecting lines of communication between Japan and Russia, and China and Korea (the Yokohama-Shanghai, the Kobe- Korea, the Kobe-North China, Kobe-Korea-North China, and the Kobe-Vladivostok routes) and between Japan proper and Hokkaido (the Kobe-Otaru and the Aomori-Muroran routes). In addition, the government decided to subsidize the regular service along the coasts of Hokkaido (between Hakodate and Nemuro, between Otaru and Wakanai, between Nemuro and Abashiri, and between Nemuro and Etorofu) from October, EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 109 1900, to September, 1905. To the Yangtze-Kiang, the Shang- hai-Soochow, and the Shanghai-Hankow steamship lines, a certain amount of subsidy was to be given every year to enable them to maintain regular sen ice. At the same time, with a view to restricting the expenditure of the fund, the government decided to subsidize only the regular service of three steamship lines, European, Seattle, and San Francisco, for ten years, i.e., from 1900 to 1909, to the extent of 2,673,894 yen for the European, 654,030 yen for the Seattle, and 1,013,- 880 yen for the San Francisco service. The government then revised the regulations so that after January, 1899, the amount of subsidy granted to ships constructed in foreign countries would be cut in half and the period of assistance lim- ited to 18 years, from October I, 1896. In addition, the government promulgated regulations for the encouragement of shipbuilding, by which ships built according to a prescribed set of regulations might receive grants, as an aid to the development of navigation. The several budgets required to carry out the foregoing plans are shown in the following table: Ship Subsidies Fiscal year Extension of steamer routes Encouragement of navigation Encouragement of shipbuilding Total 1896 1897 1898 1899 1 900 1901 1902 1903 \ t n [34.775 538,702 67 1, 3 2 1 896,898 4,205,729 5.554.440 6,387,713 6.332,44« 880,000 708,384 2,580,802 3,957,31s I. INS. 71. J 906,203 676,300 802,431 Yen 13."") 213,875 [87,380 [52,930 581,094 4H,348 437.' s «<» Yen [,01 1.775 1 ,260,195 3,46s 5,041,593 5.547,421 7.041.737 7.475.361 7.572,689 Total.. . . 24,722,026 1 1 ,700,197 1,997,546 38,419.7 SUNDRY EXPENDITURES l\ CONNECTION Willi FORMOSA 1 Formosa came into our possession as a result of the Treaty of Shimonoseki. The various expenses incurred in connect ion 'Especially those in connection with special undertakings in Formosa and in Weihaiwei. HO ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR with the island increased considerably the annual expend- iture. The expenditure in connection with Weihaiwei was that made necessary by its military occupation to guarantee the fulfilment of the Treaty of Shimonoseki. It was the sum in excess of the amount paid by the Chinese Government for the guards' service there. Article VIII of said treaty recognized the right of our army to occupy Weihaiwei as such guarantee. And in Article I of the supplementary treaty, China agreed to pay 400,000 taels as one-fourth of the expense of a temporary occupation of Weihaiwei by the Japanese Army. But as the terms of the treaty were perfectly fulfilled, and especially as the payment of the indemnity was completed May 7, 1898, this item of expense in connection with Weihaiwei became unnecessary. After that date, of the items of expense men- tioned above, those for Formosa, according to the budget for 1896, were 18,489,811 yen in all, and these are explained in detail below. The same amount has been appropriated each year ever since. Yen Civil administrative expense 5,928,705 Defense expense 7,710,481 Extraordinary Formosan expense 4,850,625 But after 1897 the annual receipts and disbursements in Formosa were turned over to a special account, with a view to making Formosa self-supporting. A reform of the govern- ment of Formosa was planned. The number of officials there was reduced, some of the government offices were abolished and some amalgamated, the ordinary administrative expenses were economized, and at the same time, an increase in revenue from Formosa was definitely anticipated. Further, new local taxes were collected, thereby considerably assisting the finances of Formosa. Consequently, the relief fund in the Treasury for administrative expenses, which had amounted to six million yen, as we mentioned before, was reduced to three million yen in 1899. It was gradually reduced after that until in 1 910 it ceased to exist. While therefore the ordinary administrative expenses of Formosa were economized so that EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FIXAXCE III Formosa was being led on to self-support, at the same time necessary enterprises in the new possessions could not he neglected. So the government decided to carry out a con- tinuation plan extending over seven years with a total ap- propriation of 35 million yen for financing various enterprises, such as (i) construction of railways, (2) investigation of land, (3) construction of harbors, and (4) building new offices for the government general. These will now be explained further. (1) A north-and-south railway in Formosa was considered a necessity from the point of view of military and industrial development. The government at first granted a permit to a private concern. But as the work was not begun at once, and there was no prospect that the railway would ever be built in this way, it was necessary for the government to build the line itself. (2) The land in Formosa had never up to this time been surveyed carefully, and land registry was in a complicated condition. Ik-sides, as there were the two systems existing of large and small leases and other peculiar conditions attached to the land, it was a very difficult task to establish a good lan< 1 system. Indeed such readjustment was impossible without a careful survey. (3) The harbors and bays of Formosa, with one or two ex- ceptions, could hardly be recognized as such, and even in the case of the exceptions, extensive work was needed to make them safe places for ships to anchor. Now after Formosa came into Japan's possession the number of ships coming and going between Japan proper and Formosa steadily increased. Not only so, but the Formosan trade gradually developed, that it became a matter of urgenl necessity to reconstruct tin- harbors and bays of the island in order to make them a safe anchorage for ships. The water works and government buildings also were of direct and indirect necessity in develop- ing Formosa. The following table gives the amounts needed for these various undertakings: 112 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Yen I ormosan railway construction and improvements . . . 28,800,000 Kielung harbor improvement 2,000,000 Temporary land survey in Formosa 3,000,000 New buildings for the Government General 1,200,000 Total 35,000,000 Table VI at the end of this chapter 1 shows the actual ex- penditure made by the Treasury for Formosa for the chief items. The actual account for the guards at Weihaiwei was 917,- 677 yen in 1896; 855,588 yen in 1897, and 85,576 yen in 1888. Besides the foregoing, the chief undertakings planned after the Sino- Japanese War were improvement of water courses, extension of educational plants, development of Hokkaido, subsidy for harbor construction, establishment of agricultural experiment stations and schools for sericulture, development of foreign trade, erection of a hall for exhibiting goods for foreign trade (after 1896), special forestry administration (after 1899), improvement of live stock, investigation of sulphur mines, establishment of industrial experiment station (after 1900), also increasing legations abroad and extending the customs service. As the government thus launched out ambitiously in various directions, the budget expanded enormously after the war. The total amount of the ordinary and extraordinary annual expenditure in 1900 amounted to nearly 300 million yew. Later, when the extension of defenses and the other continuation plan had been nearly completed, the annual expenditure for these purposes was stopped and the extraordinary expenditure was reduced. Yet before the Russo-Japanese War, that is, in 1903, the amount did not fall below 249 million yen. A part of this increased expenditure was obtained from the indemnity and a part from the bond issue, but the balance had to be taken from the ordinary revenues of the government. On that account an increase in taxes was several times required. We shall now disclose in the following chapters the sources of revenue for the foregoing various items of expenditure. 1 Post, p. 146. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC I I\ \\< 1 II Bonds and indemnity BON1N (i) War Bonds — The bonds issued to pay off the expei of the Sino-Japanese War were the so-called war bonds. The total amount of the issue was 124,920,750 yen, with net receipts to the government of 122,457,687 yen. The period of issue of these bonds stretched from September, 1894, to November, 1896. The receipts from the bond issue were used entirely for war expenses. As this has been already explained we shall not repeat the details here. But below we shall show the burden imposed upon the Treasury in conse- quence of the bond issue. Details of Bond Issle * Fiscal year Redemption of principal Interest paid Total Face value Amount paid 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1 900 Yen ^,300 940,300 2,235,200 4,889,300 [08,516,650 Yen 8,001,558 912,255 2,151,128 4,986,746 108,739,883 Yen 7 s -223 2,937,055 5,431.824 6,082,643 6,206,077 6,094,789 5,819,049 5,825,219 5,785,426 5,779,344 5. 774. 7'") 5,792,879 5,701,388 5,779,263 5,674,934 5.677.813 2,721,485 Yen 223 2,937,055 5.431 2,643 6,206,077 [4,096,347 5,8i 5,219 6,697,681 5.779.344 5.774.769 5.792 5.701 1,263 7,826 [0,664,559 1 1 1,461, 1901 1902 1903 1 904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1 909 1910 Total [24,920,750 124,791,570 87,162,1 Bo 211,953,75' » A word should be said regarding the amount paid for redemption of t he principal The amount paid was only 78,452,300 yen or the amount of the fai e value of the bonds redui ed, by purchase and exchange, by 46, 339, 271 yen. Thus the amount paid for redemption and the fa< e value of the bonds did not coincide. The net receipts were, as before stated, [22,437,687 yen, so that after all the amount paid in for redemption exceeded 9 114 ECONOMIC EFFECTS 01 THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR the net receipts by 2,353,884 yen. The net burden to the Treasury' in consequence of the war bonds issued was therefore this last figure, to which should be added 89,516,064 yen for the interest payments, and, in addition, about 500,000 yen for the cost of printing and preparing the bonds and also the expense connected with making the redemption and interest payments. (2) Sundry bond issues in connection with the post-bellum enterprises. When the government was casting about for funds to finance the post-bellum enterprises, it decided to secure such by the issue of bonds for productive enterprises, as the building of railways and extension and improvement of telephone facilities. In consequence, as we have seen, an enormous number of bonds appeared, such as the industrial bonds, the railway bonds, the Hokkaido railway bonds and the Formosan industrial bonds, which were decided upon in 1892. The industrial bonds were issued in accordance with the in- dustrial bonds act, Law No. 59, promulgated March 29, 1896, in order to secure a fund for various post-bellum enterprises. The amount was at first fixed at 135 million yen and later increased to 148,991,834 yen. This amount was apportioned to various enterprises, as follows : Nature of enterprises Amount Remarks Expense of improving government railways already built Expense of building Hokkaido rail- ways (Sorachita to Asahigawa) Expense of establishing an iron foun- dry Expense of extending telephone ex- changes Establishment of transaction office of leaf tobacco and its operating capital Expenses of army and navy extension Army 18,459,484 Navy 58,999,423 Interest on bonds for the first year. . . . Yen 26,553,000 1,178,330 3,516,031 12,802,102 12,213,550 77.458,907 1,278,080 Afterward increased one yen, i.e., 1,178,331. Afterward changed to 18,622,932 yen, i.e., an increase of 15,106,901 yen. Afterward increased 5 yen, i.e., 12,802,107 y en - Afterward 163,007 yen, i.e., a decrease of 1,115,- 073 yen- EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 115 Law No. 93, promulgated May 13, 1896, for the building of the Hokkaido railways, provided for the construction of the line from Asahigawa, Ishikari province, through Tokachida in Tokachi province, and Atsukishi in Kushiro province, to Abashiro in Kitami province; a line from Ribetsu in Tokachi province, through Ainouchi in Kitami province and Atsukishi in Kushiro province, to Xemuro in Nemuro province; a line from Asahigawa to Soya; a line from Uryu plain in Ishikari province to Masuge in Teshiwo province; a line from Xayoro in Teshiwo province to Abashiri, and a line from Otaru to Hakodate; for all of which it was decided to issue bonds to the amount of 33 million yen. Next, the object of Law Xo. 4, for railway construction, issued June 20, 1892, was to build to the limit of expenditure of 60 million yen the Central, the Hokuriku, the Kokuyetus, the Oou, the Sobu, the Joban, the Kinki, the Sanyo, the Sanin, the Shikoku, the Kyushu and other lines. Laws, Xos. 1 1 and 12, issued in March, 1895, revised LawXo. 4, and added more lines. As a result, the total amount of the appropriation was changed to 94,844,459 yen. The industrial bonds, the Hokkaido railway bonds, and the railway bonds were turned over to special accounts by Law Xo. 13, issued in February, 1899, providing for special ac- counts for these three loans. Afterwards these bonds wen called the Imperial five per cent bonds. The government now attempted to obtain a fund for Formosan development expenses by issuing bonds. Law No. 75, of March 20, 1899, provided for the issue of Formosan industrial bonds to the amount of 3,500,000 yen for the pur- pose of building railways, surveying land, constructing forts, and erecting government buildings. The foregoing four cla of bonds may be summarized a- shown in the following table. By these immense bond issues, the government tried to carry out the aforesaid plans lor new enterprises within the allotted time. But at that time the money market all over the country was very much depressed, and in consequence it was impossible to float these bonds. Therefore the money had to IK) ECONOMK llll< IS OF Till. SINO-JAPANESE WAR - of bonds First authorization Subsequent substitute authorization Yen 135,000,000 33,000,000 60,000,000 35,000,000 Yen 148,991,834 33,000,000 1 1< ik kaido Railway 94,844,459 Formosan industrial 35,000,000 Total 263,000,000 311,836,293 be transferred either from the Savings Deposits Account of the Finance Department, or from the. Indemnity Account. But in June, 1899, 10 million pounds sterling of four per cent bonds in British gold were issued (issue price, 90 per cent commission, 4 per cent net receipts, 86 per cent); and later the money collected in the Deposit Section, or bond redemption fund, was utilized in order to prosecute the work intended to be financed by the bond issues. Relation of bond issues to the expense of said enterprises. — We shall next consider the details of the amount needed for enterprises, to be prosecuted by means of the money collected by the issue of industrial, railway, and Hokkaido railway bonds, in order to show the relation of the money collected from bond issues to the total expenditure for these enter- prises. At the end of this chapter are several tables showing these details. Table VII 1 gives the revenue covering the expenditures for Formosan development for the years 1896- 1903 and includes money transferred from the general account, money transferred from indemnity, and money received from bond issues; Table VIII 2 gives the manifold purposes of the industrial bonds for the same period, and Table IX 3 gives the ratio of actual expenditures for Formosan development, also during the same period. The following table will show the amounts of interest paid on these various bond issues: 4 1 Post, p. 147. 2 Post, p. 148. 3 Post, p. 149. * The Imperial 5 per cent bonds refer to the railway, the industrial and the Hok- kaido railway bonds. The 4 per cent sterling bonds were that portion of the Imperial 5 per cent bonds issued abroad. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FIN AN* I. Interest Paid on Bonds I I Year Imperial 5 per cent bonds Formosan industrial bonds 4 per cent British sterling bonds Total 1 893-1 895.. .. 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Yen 325,626 375,ooo 1,287,979 2,840,368 2,840,408 3,031,241 3,276,790 4,127.194 5,967,454 Yen 39,215 160,812 347,283 443,018 Yen 3,913,203 3,907,816 3.907.934 3,916,066 Yen 325,626 - 000 1,287,979 2,840,368 2.^40,408 6.983.659 7,345.418 8.382.41 1 10.326,538 Total. . . . 24,072,060 990,328 15,645,019 4".7"7.407 The interest payments amounted to 40,707,407 yen. In ad- dition, a certain amount of expense was incurred in transferring money from one bureau to another account, or in borrowing for the purpose of utilizing the money temporarily as capital. Of the amount accounted for in the foregoing paragraph, exclusive of interest payments on the bonds, the total between the years 1896 and 1903 was 451,281,722 yen. The sources from which it was obtained are as follows. It must be noted, however, that the fractions of one yen were discarded, so that the detailed figures will not coincide exactly with the total. Amount transferred from the Yen Percent Yen Percent general accounts 76,4851178 ' Indemnity transferred [74,875,542 38 75 Amount secured from bond issues: [ndusl rial bonds 138,846,215 ,v>77 Railway bonds 56,106,884 12 13 Hokkaido railway bonds ... 4,967,900 1.10 199,921,000 \\ .;" As shown in the foregoing table, the percentage obtained from the various bond issues i<> the total needed \\.i- 44-,v> per c.nt, the balance having been transferred from the in- demnity (38.75 per cent) and from the general account (16.95 per cent ), but these bonds were not all issued at home. About half of them, that is, 83,96] ,800 yen, were issued abroad. Furthermore, the money which was not obtained abroad was Il8 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR secured by transfer from the Treasury surplus or from special account of the indemnity and applied to the prosecution of various undertakings, as we have explained before in detail. Thus, we should note that the funds for the chief ex- penditure for the various enterprises undertaken after the Sino-Japanese War were furnished by the indemnity and its transfer and the importation of foreign capital. The success- ful importation of foreign capital was possible, it is needless to say, because the position of Japan in the world had been raised by the Sino-Japanese War; but it was also due, we believe, to the reform of the currency system. This currency reform in 1897 was completed largely by means of the in- demnity, as we shall explain elsewhere. When we consider this matter, we should remember that the post-bellum enter- prises had a very close connection with the indemnity. That the government undertook these various aggressive post-bellum enterprises at all was due entirely to the indemnity. Here let us glance at the disposition made of the indemnity which furnished so great a service to the post-bellum finance of our country. INDEMNITY As a result of the Sino-Japanese War, an indemnity was obtained from China for four purposes, namely, for war expenses ; for interest on the deferred payments of the indem- nity; for expense of guards at Weihaiwei, and for compensa- tion for the return of the Liaotung peninsula. The claim for indemnity for war expenses and for interest on deferred payments was based on the Treaty of Shimonoseki signed April 17, 1895, Article IV of which reads as follows: China promises to pay to Japan 200,000,000 taels in Kuping silver as an indem- nity for war expenses . . . against any unpaid portions of the indemnity after date of first payment (that is the payment of 50,000,000 taels made within six months after the ratification of the treaty of peace) interest at the rate of 5 per cent per annum shall be paid; provided, however, that China may at any time pay the whole or a part of the indemnity in advance of the dates of payment; if the whole of the indemnity shall be paid within three years after the ratification of the treaty (or by May 8, 1898) all interest on the deferred payments of the indemnity shall be waived, and the interest already paid up to that time shall be included in the payment of the principal. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 119 The claim for the indemnification of the expenses of the guards at Weihaiwei was based upon Article YIII of the Shimonoseki Treaty of Peace, as mentioned before, which reads thus: China agrees to the temporary occupation of Weihaiwei in the province of Shantung by the Japanese army as a guarantee that the terms of this treaty shall be observed faithfully . . . and also upon Article I of a separate agreement which stipu- lates — The size of the Japanese Army which shall occupy Weihaiwei temporarily in accordance with Article VIII of the treaty signed today shall not exceed one Jap- anese Army Corps. China agrees to pay 500,000 tads [Raping silver) a year, as one-fourth of the expense of the temporary occupation, beginning from the day said treaty shall be ratified and copies exchanged. The compensation for the return of the Liaotung peninsula was based upon Article II of the treaty concerning the return of that peninsula which was signed November 8, 1895, and reads : The Chinese Government agrees to pay to the Japanese Imperial Government up to November 16, 1895, the sum of 30 million taels (Kuping silver), as a compen- sation for the return of the southern part of Mukden province. As the Chinese Government paid in full the entire amount of the war-expense indemnity by May 8, 1898, as stated before, the interest was waived in accordance with the terms of the treaty, as explained before. Consequently, our country received the following amounts as a result of the war: Funds In Chinese currency In Japanese currency Taels 200,000,000 ;><>,ooo,ooo I o< 10,000 Yen 311,072,865 Compensation for the return of the Liao- 44. ( ' (, 7.499 Expense of guards at Weihaiwei for three 2,380,103 Total 2.; 1.500,000 $,360,467 Interest for the use of the indemnity fund -.-- \ 231,500,000 367,248,691 120 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Considering the financial and economic condition of our country at the time, the foregoing was indeed an enormous amount, and provided funds for various undertakings after the Sino-Japanese War, such as the improvement of the national defenses and other enterprises; it also led to the expansion of our annual budget. This is the reason why we have presented here in such detail the receipts and expendi- tures in connection with the indemnity and the effects of the same upon our finance and economy. Our government, in laying financial plans after the Sino- Japanese War in reference to the indemnity, decided on the policy of applying it to the redemption of the expenses of the Sino-Japanese War, the extension of the army and navy, the establishment of an iron foundry, an extraordinary reserve fund, and a subsidy to the Bank of Agriculture and Industry, thereby laying a foundation for extensive post-bellum enter- prises. At the same time, the indemnity was placed under "special accounts," and separated from the general accounts of the government. We shall here enumerate the ways in which the indemnity was used. The amount available for various enterprises was 364,868,- 587 yen, but the fund for the expense of the guards at Wei- haiwei was from the first placed under "general accounts" and was separated from the indemnity account for war expenses. Enterprises for which Sino-Japanese War Indemnity was Employed Yen (1) Redemption of the expenses of the Sino-Japanese War 78,957,165 (2) Expenditure for army expansion 56,781,708 (3) Expenditure for naval expansion 139,157,097 I Expenditure for establishing an iron foundry 579,702 (5) Extraordinary war expenses for the year 1897 and for trans- portation and communication 3,214,485 (6) Transferred to general accounts for the year 1898 12,000,000 (7) Transferred to the Imperial Household 20,000,000 (8) Supplementary fund for warships and torpedoes 30,000,000 (9) Education fund 10,000,000 (10) Reserve fund for calamities 10,000,000 Total 360,690,2 1 7 Amount available ' 364,868,587 Amount employed for enterprises 360,690,217 Balance (transferred to consolidation fund of national bonds) . . 4,178,370 EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINAN< E 121 The details of the revenue and expenditures are shown in Table X and XI at the end of this chapter. 1 Of the foregoing, the amount used for the redemption of the war expenses, that is, 78,957,165 yen, was certainly used in accordance with the original purpose of the indemnity. Not only so, but it had a very salutary effect in the prosecution of the bond policy after the war. At first it was the plan to use the indemnity received in 1895, amounting to 120 million yen, for the first period of army and navy expansion. But at that time there was urgent need of issuing bonds or borrowing to the amount of 100 million yen for the special account of the Sino- Japane^e War, as this amount had to be secured before March, 1896. Now, if the whole of the war indemnity received had been devoted to the purposes of army and navy expansion and the fund for the Sino- Japanese War expenses had been obtained by means of bond issues, the major part of the indemnity would have been buried in the Treasury tor three or four years, while all the time the bonds would have been drawing interest — economically, a very wasteful arrange- ment. Besides, it would not appear technically correct to devote the indemnity obtained from China to expansion of means of defense, without using any portion of it for the redemption of the expenses of the Sino-Japanese War. Thus the original plan was dropped and, as mentioned before, the amount drawn from the indemnity, while the war bonds were not issued, thereby adjusting the matter of the war expenses. By these methods the load on the Treasury and the danger of disturbing the financial market after the war on account of such bond issue were avoided. So the less apparent advantages secured by this change of policy must not be ignored. Now, regarding the 20 million yen presented to the Imperial household in 1898, the government had already decided upon it in a cabinet meeting and was aboul to introduce a bill to that effect in the National Diet, when the Diet with a unan- imous vote passed a resolution of it-- own accord to present 1 Post, 1 1. 150. 122 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR tli is amount. This was an expression of the loyalty of our nation to the Imperial household ; and the fact that the nation did not spend for administrative purposes all of the indemnity from the war, but presented a part of it to the Imperial household in order to help toward perpetuating the glory of the Empire, should be displayed in special type. In present- ing it the government used consolidating bonds (face value 21,022,350 yen, market value 19,404,050 yen, and war bonds (face value 645,450 yen, market value 595,905 yen), so that these bonds helped the money market both directly and indirectly. The three funds of which this was the foundation, amount- ing in all to 50 million yen, were as follows: Item Gold coin and bullion Imperial Government bonds Cash Total Amount Face value Fundfor rebuild- ing of battle- ships and tor- pedo boats . . . Educational fund Reserve fund for natural disas- ters Yen 15,041,827 Yen 14.958,173 9,999-989 9-999,989 Yen a 10,775-850 10,775.850 Yen 1 1 11 Yen 30,000,000 10,000,000 10,000,000 Total 15,041,827 34,958,151 22 50,000,000 "Face value, £1,700,000. The greater portion of these funds was in bonds. The gold coins and the gold bullion, amounting to 15 million yen, were deposited with the Bank of Japan with the understand- ing that when the specie reserve should be reduced to 90 million yen, or when the government should have need, the amount deposited should be returned to the government. Thus it had a favorable effect upon the money market. Not only so, but at the time of the Russo-Japanese War this EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 1 23 special fund was transferred and used for war expenses, thereby affording considerable assistance to the government, which fact should be mentioned here. The foregoing were thcundertakings forwhichthe indemnity was actually used. But the influence of the indemnity upon our finance and economy was not confined to these uses. It has been skilfully manipulated to serve in many other im- portant ways; for example, after it was received and until it was finally disposed of, the balance in hand had a favorable effect upon the money market; then again, in order to prevent the outflow of our specie it was used as a reserve for exchange transactions; then in 1898, when bonds could not be issued at home, it was employed temporarily by a system of transfer; and finally it has helped the finances of Japan directly and indirectly by enabling the government to hold securities in England. Thus, while it may be out of place to go into detail regarding these matters in the present discussion, it is perhaps important to add this explanation to maintain a proper balance in point of relative importance of this and other effects. The first thing to set forth is the service of the indemnity in assisting the establishment of the gold standard system. Our country, as we shall explain later, 1 long since tried to reform our currency system and to change from the double or silver standard to the gold standard. In October, 1893, a committee was organized to investigate the advantages and disadvantages of such a change and earnestly to prepare for it. But the government could not make the change for a long time because the necessary gold reserve could not be secured. When we received the indemnity from China after the Sino- Japanese War it was arranged to receive the payment in British gold. Therefore the specie and gold bullion in payment were shipped here from England and ( >urg< >ld a >ins were minted from this, therel >y rendering practical >le the plan < >f estal dishing the gold standard. Here, however, we must explain clearly that 1 Infra, p. I 59. 124 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR in executing this plan the indemnity itself was not used — the coin was merely manipulated to produce this desired result. Then again, the temporary balance from the indemnity ac- counts was invested in securities, thus employing it for the relief of the money market. This step had been highly con- tributory toward the betterment of our finances. For instance, in the first place, in March, 1899, war bonds to the amount of 10 million yen were issued, but the result of the subscriptions was not favorable, only 1,500,000 yen being subscribed for. So 5 million yen out of the remainder of the bonds was subscribed for at face value by the government and later these war bonds were exchanged for the railway bonds held by the Savings Deposits Bureau. The railway bonds, together with the industrial bonds, were later called 5 per cent bonds. On January 21, 1898, both the industrial and the railway bonds (face value 10,807,350 jew, issue price 10,168,636 jew) were subscribed for on March 29 at a face value of 5 million yen — issue price 4,510,500 yen. The stringency of the money market after the war did not permit the issue of these bonds in open market. Yet if this capital could not have been obtained, the various undertakings would have had to be postponed. Besides, difficulties in economic circles were at that time increasing more and more. So the government, in order to relieve the market and at the same time to manipulate the indemnity successfully, decided to purchase 15 million yen of the Hypothec debentures and 35 million yen of public loan bonds, which were purchased at 96 yen per 100 yen of face value. Of the foregoing, the subscription for the Hypothec deben- tures was made to help extend the loans of the Hypothec Bank of Japan and also to relieve the industrial concerns in Osaka and other places which were in serious financial difficulties at that time. The conditions of the government subscription were that the government should take up the remainder of the whole amount of the bond issue after the popular subscriptions to the bonds had been taken into account, and that the in- I i i l< is o\ PUBLIC FINANCE 125 vestment of the capital should be confined to export industries in Osaka, Kyoto and Tokyo, or to goods which would take the place of imported articles. The actual result of the sub- scription was as follows: No. Date Total amount of loan Private subscription Absorbed 1>\ indemnity accounts Total issue 1 2 3 4 5 April 11-22, 1898 April 25-28, 1898 fune 8-13, l8 98 Oct. 1-10, 1898 April 1-30, 1899 Total Yen 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 1 ,000,000 2,000,000 1 ,000,000 Yen 477. ''5" 44.750 12,750 i.H.C'ioo 305,620 Yen 519.45" 955.250 987,250 586,100 694,380 IV;; 17.100 1 .' H >O,000 I .000,000 2,000,000 1 ,000,000 6,000,000 2,254.07.. 3.742,430 5,997,IOO It is plain, therefore, that about 62 per cent of the entire amount of the bond issue of 6 million yen was absorbed by the indemnity accounts. Next, we shall note the circumstance - surrounding the purchase by the government of the bonds. On April 15, 1898, for the first time an order was issued to the Bank of Japan to undertake the purchase ot the bonds. The result was very successful, so that in October of the same year the money market was gradually relieved and the interesl rate of the Bank of Japan was reduced. Therefore on ( October 10, the order to purchase the bondswas rescinded. The entire amount of the bonds thus purchased at that time was 38,707- 770 yen (face value) the purchase price being 36,998,826 yen. Again, on April 13, 1899, in order to raise the price of bonds, the government decided to purchase an additional 5 million yen of bonds, and thereby succeeded in raising the market price to the lace value between April 21 and June 1 of the same year. We have so far described how the government purchased the negotiable instruments for the purpose of relieving the money market. Weshallno'w shou in the following table the amount of the subscription by the government for these bonds and the amount of purchase: 126 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Government Subscription and Purchase of Bonds Item S per cent bonds: Face value Purchase value. . War bonds: Face value Purchase value . . Consolidated bonds: Face value Purchase value . . Navy bonds: Face value Purchase value. . Kinroku bonds: Face value Purchase value . . , Total: Face value Purchase value . . . Amount of subscription Yen 20,807,350 19.679.136 20,807,350 19,679,136 Purchase to relieve money market Yen 2,700 2,527 13.446,550 12,897,288 21,022,350 20,146,346 426,000 402,045 3,810,170 3,550,620 38,707.770 36,998,826 Purchase to preserve market value Yen 638,600 638,683 1,350,800 1,340,360 1,989,400 1,979,043 Exchange with deposits section Yen 3,100,000 2,966,268 3,100,000 2,966,268 Total Yen 13,910 150 22,647.931 14,085,150 13,535,971 22,373,150 21,486,706 426,000 402,045 3,810,170 3.550,620 64,604,520 61,623,273 Increase of taxes and development of government monopoly The expenses of the Sino- Japanese War were principally met by the issue of bonds and the transfer of the indemnity, thus rendering the increase of taxes in the main unnecessary. But when the government expenditure increased on account of various post-bellum undertakings, funds were secured by increasing certain classes of taxes, by creating others, and by establishing a monopoly on leaf tobacco. An increase in the taxes took place twice after the Sino- Japanese War. The estimated amount of revenue from the increase was as follows: in the first period, from the fiscal year 1896, the amount was 33,576,293 yen; in the second, from the fiscal year 1899, it was 40,346,875 yen; in all, 73,923,168 yen. According to the first plan, a business and a registry tax were newly established, a tobacco monopoly also, and the sa he tax was increased, while on the other hand certain classes of taxes were abolished. The intention was to in- crease the net receipts to over 26 million yen. The receipts were estimated as follows: EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 1 27 Estimated receipts Yen Registry tax (new) ("in force from April 1, 1 896; 6,423,993 Business tax (new) in force from January I, 1897) 7.551.377 Sake tax (increased) (in force from October 1, 1896) 9,284,544 Leaf tobacco monopoly (newly established) (in force January 1, 1898) 10,316,379 Total 33.576,293 Decrease from abolition of certain taxes 7.55 2 .397 Balance 26,023,896 Later, at the time of the second increase, a tax on tonnage was established, and other taxes were increased, in order to obtain a total of 42 million yen a year. Yen Land tax (in force from January 1, 1899) 8,475,958 Income tax (in force from April 1, 1899) 1,494,516 Sake tax (in force from January 1, 1899) 22,556,409 Tonnage tax (in force from August 4, 1899) 237,986 Registry tax (in force from April 1, 1899) 1,846,759 Leaf tobacco monopoly receipts (in force from April 1, 1899) . 2,145,550 Tax on convertible bank notes (in force from April I, 1899) . . 1,159,560 Soy tax (in force from March 1, 1899) 1.598,387 License to sell tobacco (in force from April 1, 1899) 831,750 Total 40.346.875 The entire increase for the two periods was roughly es- timated at 73,923,000 yen. Comparing this amount with the total amount of 156,552,359 yen from taxes, stamp receipts, and the profits of the leaf-tobacco monopoly for the fiscal year 1900, the year in which the entire actual amount of the increased taxes was to be realized, the estimated amount a- mentioned above was about 50 per cent of the entire amount , and compared with 74,697,624 yen, which was the amount of revenue from taxes as actually accounted for in the fiscal year 1895, the year previous to the increase in taxrs, it i> seen t<> be nearly the same as the entire amount of the tax revenues. We thus see how extraordinary the increase in taxes was. For, whereas in 1895 the amount of revenue from various taxes classed as indirect was 34,507,661 yen, against the total amount of revenue of 40,189,963 yen from the land and ine< >me taxes classed as direct, in 1900 the indirect taxes amounted to 74,788,744 yen and the direct taxes to 59,137,351 yen. The 128 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR ratio of these taxes to the entire revenue from all the taxes was as follows for [895 and 1900: Year Direct Indirect Per cent Per cent 1895 53-8 46.2. 1900 44.2 55-8 We shall explain later what kinds of taxes were classed as indirect, for we must note that these indirect taxes constituted one cause of the extraordinary rise in the prices of commodities after the Sino-Japanese War. We shall explain this point more in detail, under the heading "Fluctuation in Prices" in Chapter VIII. We have thus briefly outlined the plan to increase taxes and the results. The reason why taxes, increased once in 1896, were, within a few years, that is, in 1899, again enormously increased was because of the extraordinary increase in the ordinary expenditure arising from the post-bellum enterprises, the rise in prices consequent upon the economic changes made after the war, and the various enterprises undertaken in the newly acquired territories, since not only were there limitations to the use of the indemnity but there were diffi- culties in obtaining funds for ordinary expenditure, as the market conditions of the country at the time did not permit the sale of bonds. Naturally, these financial difficulties led to frequent political quarrels and change of cabinets. The national Diet was next dissolved so that the results just stated could be brought about. Before briefly explaining the newly established and increased taxes, we shall present the annual financial status in outline. We have repeatedly explained before that, in order to meet the various expenditures required by the nation's develop- ment after the Sino-Japanese War, and also to meet the ex- panded administrative expenditure resulting from the rise in prices of commodities and in the cost of labor consequent upon the economic disturbances after the war, our country levied increased taxes to meet the ordinary expenditure and trans- ferred the indemnity and issued bonds to obtain financial EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINAN< 1 129 resources for the extraordinary' expenditure. But as it was expected that in the fiscal year 1896 there would be a deficit of about 20,360,000 yen in the ordinary revenues owing to various expenditures, such as those for the expansion of the means of national defense, the payment of the principal and interest on the war bonds, the Imperial grants of rewards, the annual pensions, the expenditure for Formosa and for Wei- haiwei, etc., and also that these various expenses would in- crease thereafter, it was estimated that the amount needed to supply the deficit in the annual revenue would be approxi- mately 30 million yen. Hence as we stated before, a registry tax and a business tax were newly established, a leaf tobacco monopoly was instituted, and the sake tax was increased, so that in all an increase of 26,023,896 yen from taxes was secured. Although the increase in taxes was thus effected, yet in that fiscal year the revenue from the registry tax amounted to only about 2,720,000 yen (deducting the revenue from abolished taxes). The deficit so caused was made good by transferring an equal amount from the surplus in the Treasury left over from the previous year, the government being thereby barely enabled to balance the annual revenue and expenditure. The next year, 1897, the budgetary item for expenditure was also enormously increased. But, as tin- increase in taxes had been effected in the previous fiscal year. there was a revenue of 16 million yen from the increase (net revenue about 10 million yen after deducting the revenue from abolished taxes), and in addition a natural increase in revenue from other sources; so that the ordinary revenue for that year showed an increase of about 20 million yen compared with the previous year, thereby enabling the government to maintain a reasonable balance between the annual revenue and expenditure. But until the succeeding year the entire estimated amount of revenue from the increased or newly established taxes could not be obtained. So the deficit was supplied from the surplus in the Treasury and from a certain amount transferred from the indemnity. But in 1898, owing, on the one hand, to an extraordinary increase in expenditure 130 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANKSK WAR (amounting to about 5 million yen) for the encouragement of water transportation, the extension of shipping routes, and the replenishment of the fund for various enterprises in Formosa (amounting to about 10 million yen) and on the other hand, to a decrease in revenue (amounting to about 5 million yen), because of the abolition of the tax on registry of population, the decrease of the business tax, etc., there was again a deficit in the ordinary revenue amounting to 21 million yen. There- upon, the government tried to secure the entire amount or an increase of 25 million yen from the land and sake taxes. But the net revenue from increased taxes for the fiscal year 1898 amounted to only a little more than 8 million yen. The revenue for this year included about 9,500,000 yen of the increase in the land tax, but 170,000 yen were expended for the collection of the revised sake tax, and 910,000 yen for the ex- penses of land revaluation, while 330,000 ;yew were estimated as a decrease through the prohibition of home sake brewing. It was planned to meet the deficit thus caused by means of a loan. But at that time, the government — the Matsukata Ministry — lost control of the political situation. The Diet did not approve the ministry, and passed a resolution to that effect. Thereupon the Diet was dissolved and at the same time the bill to increase the tax was voted down. Conse- quently, the only way to supply the deficit was to make use of the indemnity or temporary loans. Thus, in a short time, the Matsukata Ministry fell, and the second Ito Ministry was formed. The new Diet formed after the dissolution was commanded to assemble May 19, 1898. In that year, as before stated, there was a deficit in the annual revenue and the disparity between revenue and ex- penditure was great. As it was plain that this situation would be continued into the following year, the government again planned an increase in the taxes in order to be ready to meet any emergency. It was estimated that the deficit in the ordinary revenue would be 35 million yen as itemized on the next page. So, the government, to offset this deficit, tried to obtain an EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE I3I Yen Sundry* expenses in Formosa 1 1 ,240,000 Encouragement of water transportation and extension of shipping routes 4,870,000 Redemption of bonds 7,000,000 Prison expenses paid out of Treasury 3,550,000 Fund established for relief of sufferers from natural disasters 500,000 Interest on Chitsuroku bonds • ',000 Increase in the ordinary expenditure on account of the rise in prices. . 6,860,000 New enterprises on account of revision of treaties with foreign countries 2,550,000 Total 37,0.-50,000 Excess of revenue 1 .500,000 Balance (deficit in revenue) 35, 530,000 increase in revenue from the land tax of 17,550,000 yen, the income tax of 1,640,000 yen, and the sake tax of 12,410,000 yen, totaling 31,600,000 yen. In addition, an increase was planned from the telegraph services, 430,000 yen, from the railway profits, 3,240,000 yen, totaling 3,600,000 yen, which would bring the grand total of increase to 35,200,000 yen. But the Diet considered it unreasonable to deliberate upon an increase in annual revenue not accompanied by corresponding expenditure. Therefore, the bill for revision of the land tax regulations was rejected by a great majority on June 10, 1898. The Diet was again dissolved, and the Ito Ministry fell on June 30. The Okuma Ministry which succeeded also fell on October 31 of the same year, on account of troubles among the members of the party, and was followed by the Yamagata Ministry. In reviewing the budget for the year 1899, we find thai the revenue amounted to 188,738,437 yen and the expenditure to 226,344,792 yen, the deficit in revenue being 37,606,355 yen. The following are the principal items of increase in the or- dinary expenditure which account for this deficit : Encouragement of water transportation and extension <>f shipping routes 3,790,462 Sundrj expenses in Formosa 12,121,597 Army expenses ■ .-75 3 10 Navy expenses ,v57~ Army expansion 5,1 (.0,798 I emporary repair of warships and torpedoes \ )<> ).;- Sundry expense- in connection with revision ol treaties and execu- tion of laws in pracl ice 1,961,425 Sundry expenses for education 1 508,310 Increase in expenditure of various government departments 6,141,562 fotal 35.95 132 ECONOMIC II I l< IS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR There was also urgent need for effecting the payment of prison expenses out of the treasury reserve and for establish- ing a fund for the relief of sufferers from natural disasters. For these purposes, the sum of 46 or 47 million yen was required, but as the indemnity had already been allotted to various uses, only a very small amount remained available. As for a new bond issue, that was out of the question at this time when the money market was so tight. But as the fore- going items were practically of the nature of ordinary expend- iture, a second period of tax increase was planned. Ac- cordingly, the rates on land, income, sake, registry, convertible bank notes, soy, and tobacco business were raised, the rate of revenue from the leaf -tobacco monopoly was increased, and a revenue from postoffice and telegraph service was planned, amounting in all to 42,020,219 yen. These taxes have been discussed before, but we may here mention the fact that in anticipation of the proceeds to result from the new tax law the deficit in the annual revenues was made up by a transfer of a part of the indemnity. The first increase in taxes yielded 33)576,293 yen additional revenue, the second, 42,020,219 yen, a total of 75,596,512 yen. But in the early part of 1900 the Boxer troubles occurred in China and on June 26 of the same year Imperial Emergency Ordinance No. 277 was issued, authorizing the government to use, for the Boxer punitive expedition, a part of the three funds which had been estab- lished with the indemnity obtained from China, viz., (1) for building warships and torpedo boats, (2) for meeting emer- gencies from natural disasters, and (3) for promoting education. Before the end of 1900, 28 million yen from these funds had been employed for the aforesaid purpose. Accordingly, in 1 901, an attempt was made to repay the Boxer expenditure and reimburse these three funds by raising the taxes on sake and sugar and raising, or at least regulating, the customs tariff rates, since it had been decided to replace revenue raised from bond issues with that raised from taxation. It was decided to raise additional revenue from the leaf -tobacco monopoly also. The bill to increase the taxes was vigorously EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FIN AM I 1 33 opposed for a time by the House of Peers. But after an Imperial order had been issued, the bill was successfully passed, and the various bills as passed were put in force from October i , 1 90 1 . As stated before, the increase in taxes for the year 1901 was planned principally for the purpose of repaying the ex- penses of the Boxer war. But as the expenditure of the money thus raised was not confined to this, a further increase soon became necessary. Such were the evil effects of the post-bellum enterprises. We shall here tabulate the increase from the various taxes as follows : Yen Beer tax 229,047 Revised tariff regulations 141.374 Sugar consumption tax 2,718,867 Leaf-tobacco monopoly price changed 3,204,287 Total 6,293,575 This increase amounted to about 6 million yen so that the whole increase reached about 82 million yen. We shall leave the detailed explanation concerning the foregoing various kinds of taxes to the volume dealing with the investigation of taxes and shall here confine ourselves to saying a few- words concerning the development of government enterprises. After the Sino-Japancse War, the newly planned or ex- tended government enterprises were the tobacco monopoly, the railways, the iron foundry, and the post and telegraph offices. The reasons for starting said enterprises were as follows: The iron foundry was considered indispensable for defense purposes, the extension of the railways was planned in order to develop the wealth of the nation, and as to tin- reform in the regulations for postal and telegraphic service and railway freight made in the year 1899, this was made for quite other purposes than the replenishment of the annual revenues. The leaf-tobacco monopoly, on the other hand, was started altogether for the replenishment of the annual revenues, and was the first of the monopolistic enterprises undertaken by Japan. As we have already briefly described the iron foundry in discussing the extension of national defenses, and shall [34 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR explain the extension of railways in Chapter VI, we shall here dwell chiefly upon the leaf- tobacco monopoly. The leaf-tobacco monopoly is especially notable for two reasons, first, because out of the entire budget the amount secured from its revenues was the largest in the financial program hurriedly formulated after the Sino-Japanese War 1 (in the first period of tax increase, 10,316,379 yen; in the second period, 2,145,550 yen, total 12,461,929 yen), and second because with its institution the monopoly system was first established as a government enterprise. It may indeed be proper to discuss the subject here as one development of government enterprises; but especially because it belongs to the class of consumption taxes, it is explained here. The leaf-tobacco monopoly was established to replace the stamp tax on manufactured tobacco provided for in the tobacco-tax law of 1876. The annual revenue from the stamp tax had been very small, in 1876 amounting to only 80,000 yen. Later, it increased to between 50,000 yen and 60,000 yen for about seven years. In 1884, as a result of the revision of the law, the revenue reached approximately 1,000,- 000 yen, and after the revision of 1889, between 1,500,000 yen and 2,300,000 jew. But if the rate of a tax be raised the tax is liable to be dodged and the object — to secure an increase in revenue — frustrated. Thus the tobacco monopoly came to be established, with the object of controling the sale legally. The government was to supervise the raising of tobacco, and the tobacco raisers to secure a special permit from the government to raise tobacco and to sell the crop to the government, after inspection, before harvesting or after the crop had been dried. They were not permitted to dispose of this to private parties or to consume it privately, and the government, after purchasing, was to sell to the tobacco manufacturers, thereby securing a margin of profit. This plan was executed from January 1, 1898, in accordance with Leaf-Tobacco Monopoly Law No. 35, promulgated on March 27, 1896. 1 Article 12, Leaf-Tobacco Monopoly Law Xo. 35. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 135 To be more specific, the government had the privilege of mo- nopolizing the sale of all the leaf tobacco produced but must sell the produce at a fair price, the producers being required to report their, products to the government. The produce left over in the hands of the tobacco manufacturers 1 ief< »re January I, 1898, which was the date of the execution of the new law, was to be governed l>y the tobacco tax law in force before that date. But at that time, the import tariff rate of our country was very low in accordance with the old treaty stipulations, so the importation of foreign tobacco increased considerably; the more so as the direct exportation of leaf tobacco was permitted to the producer without first selling it to the government. l Unscrupulous merchants often took advantage of this right and thus the desired result of the monopoly system could not be obtained. Therefore, on January 1 , 1 899, the tariff law was reformed and the existing evils removed, as by Law No. 28, issued on March 1, 1899, the government was to buy or import leaf tobacco. Again, the manufacture of tobacco or the monopolistic sale of leaf tobacco was permitted to those securing a license issued on payment of a fee (in the case of manufacturers, 50 yen each for manufactures, and 50 yen each for dealers). This was done to increase the revenue by raising the rate. The government, as a basis for estimating the profit from the monopoly, fixed the average price of manufactured tobacco throughout the country in 1894 at 22 sen per 100 momme (1 momme = 58 grains troy). From this four sen, four rin, and two mo of stamp tax was deducted, ><> that the net market price was fixed at 17.5s sen. Since 100 momme of manufactured tobacco requires 14.S0" momme of leaf tobacco as material, at the aforementioned market price loo momme of leal tobacco would be worth 12.157 sen. The rate of revenue for the government from this was fixed at 55 per cent so that the amount of revenue for the government was 4.248 sen. But the average selling price of leaf tobacco by the growers was lived at 5.084 sen per 100 1 Article 1^, Leaf-Tobacco Monopoly I aw No. 35. I,V> I ( ONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR momme. The following table will show the basis of monopoly ]> rices: Sen Profit of the treasury (35 per cent.) 4.248 ( ommission for brokers for transportation (1 1 per cent.) ....... 1 .026 Sundry manufacturing expenses (about 20 per cent.) 2 .000 Profit of the manufacturers and of the dealers (33 per cent.) . . . . 4 .027 Total 16.385 If this total is compared with the price of leaf tobacco, that is 12.137 sen > to which the stamp tax of 3.034 sen must be added, making a total 15. 171 sen, it will be seen that as a result of the tobacco monopoly established by the government the market price would become higher by about 1.2 14 sen. Now, according to the estimate of the government, the entire production of leaf tobacco throughout the country amounted to 24,285,260.182 kwan 1 and at the rate of 4.248 sen of profit per 100 momme for the government, as per the fore- going table, the revenue of the government, it was estimated, would be 10,316,379 yen. But the actual results of the monopoly did not come up to this estimate, as will be shown below. In the year 1901 the profits of the government amounted to 10,866,699 y en > but if we remember that the rate of profit then was 150 per cent, we may realize what the situation was. The annual amount of leaf tobacco produced throughout the country for several consecutive years was as follows: Amount produced Amount received by government Price paid by government Price per kwan 1898 Kwan 8,280,882 ' 13,714,724 13,315.291 8,484.374 8,349.505 11,506,790 Kwan 8,177,711 13,493.327 13.309.991 8,626,506 8,430,071 11,474,249 Yen 5.967,625 8,039,214 7,720,610 5,792,281 6,123,339 8,660,353 Yen 0.730 0596 0.580 0.671 1899 1900 1901 1902 0.726 0-755 1903 Total 63,651,566 63.5u.855 42,303.422 1 1 kwan = S\ lbs. av EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 137 Now the rate of revenue was based upon 84 per cent of the purchase price paid (the monopoly on imported tobacco was commenced from 1899 and the purchase price was based upon the same). Later, from July, 1898, to August, 1900, the rate increased to 100 per cent; from August 22, 1900, to 130 per cent; in the year 1901 it was 150 per cent; and in the year 1902 between 140 and 180 per cent. The amount and the percentages of profit are given below, in a table which will show that the estimated revenue was at last obtained in the year 1902. Expense of procuring leaf tobacco Profit Percentage of profit 1897... 1898. . . 1899... 1900. . . 1901 . . . 1902. . . 1903- •• Total Yen 375-005 5,867,618 8,040,416 8,221,584 6,840,999 6,921,933 9.743.213 Yen 292,141 5,145,999 7,559.533 7,244.159 10,868,699 12,367,569 14,898,291 Per cent 779 86.2 94.0 88.1 158.8 178.8 46,010,768 58,376,391 126.87* * Average. Now, at the time of the increase in taxes, in 1902, it was planned to obtain 1,673,344 y en from the post and telegraph revenues; while the direct object was not to replenish the annual revenue, yet the change in the telegraphic rate and the railway fare produced an increase of over 2,200,000 yen in the annual revenue. With this increase, telegraphic apparatus was increased, wires were extended, and the means of com- munication were otherwise improved in order to help the development of the government enterprises. Local Finance As the finance of the central government expanded after the Sino-Japancse War, so the expenditure of the local governments for educational and industrial development expanded proportionately, to keep pace with the national I38 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR development. The following table will show the general increase in the annual expenditures of prefectures, cities, towns and villages, which are the local self-governing units of our country. Increases in Annual Expenditures of Prefectures, Cities, Towns and Villages Fiscal year Prefectures (Do, Fu, Ken) Cities (Shi) Villages (Cho and Son) Comparison annual ex- penditure from national treasury 1 893 1 00.0 106.0 101 .2 129. 1 163.4 170.3 197-8 212.3 219.6 236.8 245 6 100. 114. 8 138.8 176.8 235-0 250.8 343-2 435 6 506.1 593 ° 589-7 100. IIO.O 119. 7 134-3 170.2 193-5 223.3 263.0 296.6 311 5 3164 100. 1894 1895 92 100 199 283 259 300 346 315 342 295 4 9 1896 9 1897 4 1898 8 1 899 5 1900 1 1901 5 1902 1903 1 As shown in the foregoing table, the expansion of the finance of the local government was much the same propor- tionately as that of the nation. In the case of cities the percentage of increase was especially great. The table on page 139 will show the percentage of various items of expenditure of the local governments to the total and also the percentage of increase in the expenditure in the year 1904 compared with that of the year 1895. 1 The table on page 139 shows that of the various items of expenditures, those for construction and for the police in prefectures, those for construction, education and bond issues in cities, those for construction, education and offices in towns and villages, amounted to enormous sums. It shows, again, 1 In the annual expenditure, prefectural expenses for sanitation are included among other items, also the prison expenses were turned over to the national dis- bursements, in the year 1902. The administration of the police and the prisons is a governmental work and does not belong to the incorporated local communities, so that these expenses of administration do not appear in the expenditure of cities, towns and villages. EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 139 Ratio of Expenditures of 1904 and Rate of Increase over 1895 Prefectural expenditure City expenditure Town and village expenditure Percentage Rate of Percentage Rate of increase Percentage Rate of increase 16.15 31-55 12.30 2.90 6.79 3.88 26.70 101 .2 148.9 659.1 8130 4104 102.9 14 32 22.05 0.36 4.81 13-53 8.49 0.58 35-87 721 .6 385 9 257 4 795 3 8051 278.4 58.7 427.5 16.51 35-82 1 .21 5 94 s'65 23.16 1.08 10.63 250.1 Encouragement of in- 504- 1 5466 Prison expenses for pre- 1.2694 Office 112. 62.3 979-2 Total 100.00 145.6 100.00 4897 100.00 216.4 that the percentage of increase was especially remarkable in educational, industrial, sanitation and bond-issue expenditure. This shows how the local governments have been endeavoring to improve education and to develop wealth to keep pace with the central government and help in the advancement of the nation. It was indeed in keeping with the general tendency to encourage the post-bellum enterprises of the nation. Table XII at the end of this chapter 1 shows the percentage of increase in educational, sanitation, industrial and bond-issue expenditure. The expenditure for education mentioned in the foregoing table refers to that of local communities, that is, for public schools and the general education of the people. The ex- penditure for sanitation was for preventing disease, for disinfection, and for arrangements for public sanitation. The expenditure for encouragement of industries was made to encourage agriculture, industry and commerce. All these were calculated to help conserve and increase the national power, but appeared in the local government budgets only in connection with the post-bellum enterprises of the nation. As for the direct financial effects of the war, there must have been various item- of expenditure, such as the expense oi 1 Post, p. 151. I40 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR farewell receptions for the soldiers who went to the front, the relief of the survivors of the dead, and other similar items, which would have increased the expenditure considerably. But the exact data are lacking and, besides, the patriotism of our countrymen, their enthusiasm to serve their country, the ardent desire of the people to relieve their own relatives, have created the sentiment that it is a great honor to die at the front and have lessened the burdens of the local government in relieving the survivors of the dead, so that it will not be far wrong to state that the expenditure for these purposes did not burden the local governments very much. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE I 4 I pq f/MO u^ri 1^0 N-tm O O " O N 1/". f3 N C 00 'too n 10 n q\ o_oo 10 1 - n B t» o« \o coo no 00 m c f*5 O NO O O rO rn O N ir-.zc O O r- HI O j» no ionooooo n m 00 £ OO 1- NCC -f C~ — '"I O rn 00 2-S-s G'C ;£, M «JN00_O *^. K c. C tn ? 3 O" m M\o" 1/5 0" ci 0" >o C 3 = — — l-l M x t^ ■ N h* O O -+ N rOO 0" ^ . . -vOvO "t^i-NN n i—i C W *C 10 ; -fir, M m c-. ir, ir. 1 ^ i - 1 -. 00" en - >> u o* **• (S 00 00 N00 ID "O n « no a 000 00 • • >r. ^, , r . z - z — ~ lO 3 SS i NffNH\0\0 fio M O ^ . . IOO tn. fi NC 't H^l h-NNOi-ii-iCOO N """" r^ C HI (ON^O HH 0" O l_ M 1—1 C C ,« c rt S C <" C N O tJ- u - ) ro N N Os d ro n tONMOO >C Tt-O IO C5 -f ICh\C O tl NOO w n O N u >> is a 15 - C tC COMMON c> k* n « no "0 c H>1 O H-l fCfO^O^HH OtN O n g22 rn ci 1/50 pi hh c"o 0" uo 00" •"""S "o -fCN-1-O IOO <*0 <*0 00 _ f) OO pi O O i--oo f) £ <-• ■ ■ >t * uj 10 000 00_ - 10 m — n N hi lOO NO 'J- C) 01 00 u ro *r> 10 -f W N N -f — - ; -+■ rt T-i '1 ION -►i.t l/J 10 <~^00 O St p and tion bom MOOOOOIOO o»o M CoonMMOOhhpsO'-' CO - N PI OO O O^pChh NOO £ " C-u h- C^ -t- 0__ M__ 0_ 00_ cc C 1 - c> c f- '1 >r. C O" -f ir: ( M-. O^O^^CT^CT^O^O O O O iz 000000000000 a>c S 142 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR y o a S D H 3 ■z a Ph w Q E <: w D W > w P4 en O ID ~ OOO O O NN-t^O ID u On O X O rO »D O l^- -1" t^ ""> ID 3 ir,0» rOX Pi H X >0 <"i C »D ro>" O NNM •+ "0 C '"i M 1^ -3 3 B u",^ ci ro— -tiAi! t -~ -i- — t- O ^ "*-oo On t-;X_ ■+ 0__0_ w 0_ i-^ ID " i-T id r-". on x" o" •+ o" ro -f ■-"■ o" a W lOlfiifivO W ON n rO -t" ID >D P» rt 1* O H p< id co too •^■co >o m m s X 00 O POX On -J- n 00 l^-t-O P< o> 3 oa>fi •* o pi t»- n it, n a\ ■* sOO n idx" pi «n r-^. t — CTN £ n coiDOnO -t"0 O **- — PI PI* 0> P>. ^ a*Nvo * \r-j\o m po on t^ pi N 0) id O T rC rf o* On C " t"~ O fO id pT o< OO^OOOOCfl -to t^ r~» X (A 01 _ m t>» h o 0*\0 M IsNm "1- 3 TfO Pi J^— K N u~ ; NvO ID Pl **• rOX n X X 0) O ^f P}. ^1" o__ D '"5 C o> 8 h \o u: n m rf o~- o" -t- m *f i-T bO H"i tJ-O » m pi +i- O ifi^O X jg ID "jj« a pi -+ O OX co O O O On " pT > V. pi ci pi ntoi-iomco r^» o ID c 03 rt-N O O ^J-l^O O X O rO ■* 0) •3- - m\0 cO O OXNH ■* PO C o H 3 OOt^nXOPlOXOcO ID C 8 pf « O P~0 i- ID PO On PI O o" 0) ■>> OX ID POO ON O i P4 POO o > "Ont> pox o o Tt- 1^ ^- po 0) ps! rJ-O X PI OO *+ PO *- ICO o PI PI PI PO •* ■* >DO t^t^.t>. ID 01 £ x" Pi" pT COX OnO >-i rr> TtiTt 00 bo .*> OnO rUDO r^POONO t^ PI i^ >*■ m pi cmcn n- icko id ON 3 o 2 a Tj- IDO t^O i-i iDO^PlOO o" o X „ — n -* 0< M PI ID 03 13 W *~ G O f>- "" O X i- On t^X "h •* PI 03 0) COO t>. i-i O ^1-PO— lOO O 3 IT5X ii n OO ON^tt^ — X * 01 3 8 o" *f « >C Pi" « vo" >o ■+ «o i" ON o> /» «X NNO i-X «OOX « o nc>«vo «ci o o ^ m t^ U > 0> 0< ID c" o" o" «"" PO >D O" "0 ON Pi" PO M PI Ol mo «ms«ifi r^o O pi PO 3 o m-i-iDPi pi oox Tj-rt- t x i/j o_ •* pi_ r-; o_ "J po o_ o> PO c •3 3 Ol 8 ro rf Pi" O t^. O X PI 0*^0 PI x" i* O O O tltHNPlMNM I^HiOOXOOt^'^-OXOii PI o> o>~* tNI a TfO rh — O - X PI rox O 5 c X «s p< cs POrhTf^-ioioioo o U ** cj 03 £ 3 OOO pi o-t-o oom-+o P) 2^ o> ox n o o> o r^x ro id pi X 3 Tl-TtrOPI — "OPIO ON lOX >* o C 8 -^ --f i/j ro O ON - ^ ro pT o" t-» pT Q o> /u h,\o rOPOPOPOr^P^iDPIX hs 00 lONO OO PI 00 i t^O PO > ID o> 05 m 0\NhC r>-o X O ID ID O POP) PI '^-'^•'1-iDiDOOO PO ID "c5 u 03 "ol E 0) POTfiDO P^X On O — PI PO O OnOnOnOnOnqnOnO O O O XXXXXXX OnOvOnOn EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FIN'AN'CE 143 en c - "o * 3 — i/^r^x x r i — C — X X t*5 3S -r ir. r. Z — C - — N r < -1" 'Z c - nniOHOoOOOOO - 1 - u >< O O \r. <-i -f ~ X C Z "". t*3 1 - r^ ex -r — 1 - m x c '■i c> w N "o 3 ir. t*J lOO^CS "". ~ X N _ c 10 1,- ir. n - c /. — r i -r -r D 1/1 ss x -t- — C - T X Z D m « lO -' I! . - H C — — t^ PI — W. - O Ch O ?■ O^O pOx" Pi" tO I^X O (N W u fi « ".- M PO bo C -t C C "~. X ir. — \r. Z — 3 q r, z — Z £ "". PI ""- ■ r ~C ~ - ""• c -r - -t- r- — --flNtOtO^ClN co U u 3 4J •a B . w x__ W 3 — od" t^O X* r^ """. Z £ £ £ lO 3 8 X tN — ""- 1^ ""- — "~- "~. '1 O 1 O 3 , \. ,r. — rooe c 1 ^ — 1 - x pi 10 ""' -f x in x "•. r- -+■ r i c r* r- °1 pT < X t^.X O (N — "■- Z C X ->- i-MNNtNNNCH N N 5J bo m 3 c «*> w -t: -tic: » Z £ -t -t Z "~. ^. Z - - ' 5 oe C- rr'ic-rotN - - - - - '1 N N PI (N u - — CJ 3 3 - > — X >M fit*! 1^ -+- x ~ -t- X c - . ^1 -i i^i £ -rn 10 (N w : 1 ~ -r — — 100c ti> -r 3 » O N ~ z' -r — -■- r 0" 3 2 c 1 " "" — Z "~- "~- ""■ " ~~ ' ■ C = . - 1 , - -r Z "". : 10 < — r — a '1 r i "". ~ > - -r „ hh ri n n '1 ^i r i ^1 ro pi - >> "3 rt 1, -' - if .- 1 . r rC— O CO MOOM'-tONOO ov o 00 O ^ •^-r0iO'^--^;C>"2r> r iO NM 01 H co o" o">00 w »/"> m ■*t\0 r-~ ov co ri- ■<*■ COO OOO O C-l C-l M CI 00 H H H M H o ■tff^iOO >-" toO «N CM i o irioo oo * ^-m M H o M\fl N ■ & u o 00 01 t^ oi i-i Ov "3- O rt 't l ~; ^^R. o_ 8 i to co N O~>oo~ to tF i-< cn ^F IO ?H m (O t^.00 iO cOO "3-vO t^ rO 00 "3 c CO S « tC i o\ cf> u-j m o n « oo" n rC N N ii cOcOcO'*rJ-'d-Tj-'0^» NtOO co Ov r^ 00 O 00 Ov Tj-vO co "~jO O *+ 00 ■tOvO O^O « N "?^~L ■* "* s» co •■*■-+ ei i -F !-"• r-"-oo n co K m N WtNO OV00 lOtOTf of ON iJ 3 O .p k^ oo o; ^ n m m « m \q q_ q_ 00 Protec enco ment ate en 1 1 1 1 ^t^C^C^'OO OC\ co rt UOCN O tON ifiO n t^t^n CO o ** co onoo oi ■* o o ov o m On 1 = ma>0 mvo o lO-^-ior^'* M 8 i-*. io i oo" co n" tF o> of oT m oo" ►5> coo to r-» ov i^ mo t>. m CO UO r>. s rC o> o"< ""> o* t-". i m c* i o «f o i 01 N CO "3" •* -d" ■* ON U o< . oo OvO ^t- Ov N Tt- n t^-rjoo ,_ I^l >0 N *h\0 N OOO PHO O o» Ov OvOO 00 to CM> (> rt N m^ o_ 8 vO coo o" o" o" Ol" tF o~ m" o" 2 C 3 R o> -a .'u uoo io io o O >i ii r^o o Pn lO CO '3-00 m m\D lO OvOO 00 "1 cS.S H * h h m to tFo ii o o~ ov o". IO w "c5 c .2 t-^ Ov OS O i "d- O ^oo co'* t^ Gs & ■* ii t^» CO00 00 rfvO t^» o O >0 'i-vO rj- O^ "1 co^O t!-v£> IO 8 m OcoO lOmOM r< nt^ o u ,^C C OMOM O^O t^ O Ps i-c n d 0<7>CSVOCN J^vO r^ 01 ON 3 m m h b n" to 'i-^ vo rC t-C "* T) Tl- W S^ 00 vO i00 O ^hO r^cO'i-'d-'d- M \D ^O 1/300 O O CO00 m\0 * O >- C ji v£> IO00 00_ t^00_ 0_ m t--. "*00_ r>. 8 rfoo" cO^o" h to h oo" h vO ^ M •2 J2'S .OiOmOmvOmOMONiO CM C T2 c Ov 2?a n" CN cT CO to to •*■ ■*■ oo* in lO COCNI^.0 con O cOO i00 -*■ b OlOO^flO O N N "tlOlO r^ >+ rf co o_ cn f^ 00 . ■* ^2 C£ ^1 O; 3 8 m"o"n r^oo"vo c^oo* •*£ c\ i-T co K ^ oo i inoo vooooionb io kH m i Tj-vO t^ r^OO NiOtOM Ov vO_ CO to to co N t^oo t>-0C oo O t-^ t^ "rt o "3 8 H to rh "IO t^OO CT> O i N CO o^c-oooo^oo o c o •- 00000000000000 O'O^OOi 1 Uh ^S E « U - •5 si o'.3 a -a EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE 145 vc <"i ex i N >- ION m pi pi -/too 00 to -* •<*• to 0" 93 M B « Oajic-tM ^f, 1- — 00 lO rO 1^ ~ -ten 1 - C c > j» "2 "2 "". ~t °. ""i ~ *2 *i •"! "i 5 u wja S n ►- pi" c to w 00" on o* N L_ "". C '"I — ir. X 00 vC CnO 00 t^ O - £ pic; — i - x m — co t->. ^ - PO — s w Pi' Pi" «tf tfl C -f -f M 00 r- b« PI 00 0*00 N 1/5 g\ tn _, « 2 C r 00" 1- -*oc_ Pl_ PI C u ON PO ■* 1-1 PI VO PI OOO POC to N >- 0^00 ON >0(ONh CO On lOOC POP! fO "(3 IfilflM 1-1 IO Tf- mOO O 00 O cj en S N *« O *N t^rl-«O000\O c? — bZ POO PI ■* to f ro PI O N t*- to H fHO h lODfl M N O P-OO 00 ~ m « W «N NOO N N m H rt 00 In is tn 3 s c c n 000 i<;o ion- n PO c iOi^Nh CO On lO 00 to rO c to to >-i •-> to -s- 1000 i>. c N 'o OJ -0 5 I-^«0 rh pi t^Tj-1-.oo t^N. On > _ sz poo pi tj- 10 -1- ro pi r- c £ pi_o_ >-<_ to c^ pi_ pi_ pi^ c s 00 o_ 2. c >-i Pi" PI r;N NOO" Pi" Pi" PO pf *£ U> H^ CH u u bo — > 1^ On en 00 00 1^. 0" 00 c c U jj «o °°. ^ O u N 00" w M CPi-i-c-tccr O 00 ON PI ONO to to r^ *rt . . •po~o-+piococoo t S . . .« ON C » h 10- 0" bo O U-i . . .OOpOiOpO'+OOn PI .S 10 H m C> PO C> to 1- 00 00 r-» *S >« p- to p6 i-T -rf po pi" pi" to .2 « pi R 9 "Ha 03 O u c C PI -*0 PI «i On c COOO OnJ^OnO PO -1- t 4_J -4-» ■ • ■ 'C--^ tt .*". n c C *3 5 ! ; ! 0" 0" pT S c" m ef pi > _ L-, . . . O C PO to PO ONO •-" to E £ E a* — 3 "~j OOO O 00 O - to ro -" PO Pi" ro O" > 1- PI c .- 1- ^ c c r l C* -■ ON lO O "". r l PO — <-~ < lO -f 1^ O h VO tJ- O^ Pi rO C ►« - Pi" to "n la 3 .i n C] -T 1/5 O t^OO On C •- pi PO >■ OnOnCnOnO^O^OnO C h ' ' 1 00 00 00 ON 146 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR en 01 u -tNO NO •tO to N CM nO_ -t tO ** t-; _ 3 M OnnO" »f 0> -f N O' T? rC rt . - S »\D N -+00 NO OO ON E- 5 a nboo n ion « 00_ 00" 00 y. 01 OOO -t^fCiONro 00 O M OnOO 00 M On -t" NO 1 tn <-> P • to On i-> On NnO fCN ON S " ^lOM'^io^om N pH 0\NN N NO " \Ti ■~ c CN1 S J3 N IO00 to C qj O ON rt en to en •.- k N C 1- u 4> ^ : on* : : : . : . to NO O tl to m •<£ Pu £ O rt to 10 ID •* N to ureau ormos Affair ^ » - to : : : to cat. CO m O m N (OLO - 10 ^ • • to 10 o_ vo q_ r>. >o 10 K) S " ' O^ rf o"oo" i-T OnOo" M O .^ ' 1000 ouno^N i-N OOs(NO(N"-iiO tN tN lO rh TJ OO f)0 N tO 0> -i-J O O 00 O »D to 'OOfiqs s • ; ; ; 0" 0" ■*■ o"oo" to ^ . . . . O O NO TfvO i-H «« 10 "4- ■*■ O hoOOO • • O "lO^vOtO NN "* c"2 S ■ ' On ^f 0~ 00~ NO~ On On 00" en 5 .<" ' 1O00 O OnOO uo iC IO CO tC (N CM CM CM ^r CnT 3 tN ifi o) 5 • U (0 n 3 tC u IO CNI O «0 fO . cn)_ w nO_ pendi Form ards, £ ' noo~ 10 cni nC n 00" .*> ON'* *1-vO ^J-00 11 Ph NO 00 On NO *N lOfO N NO f3 fO <*> * * * tO rt X u 3 to W,° M u 01 P-> ~ci (J O ICO N00 ON O — tN tO en OnOnOnOnOnO O O C 0000000000 OnOnOnOn H 1 ' = 5 ft a 3^ «W EFFECTS ON PUBLIC FINANCE U7 00 00 •- -tx — -+• M tN 10 Q e*50 COO co N NOO OO t-«. co ON PC "~. XX 1^ N 10 rO t^ X O O — -too O rl- O PQ s>* — O O t-«. "OX lO CO X rt — 10 •+ -fX 1^ x_ -+ tN 1^ 1^ — 00 t^ t>» vO* -+■ ""v -t" -t" C| O O t^ cfl m O tN co M O OX t-l X c«3 r- 1^00 tN tN CO vO~ lO a — O -4" r^ ■- tN vO 10 >n is in co O -tX O ^O 1^ tN O IOO NflOM £j O h m f( in rOX tN 0" O "i-O O tN X ID 3 **■ *4- O r-» O tN t^x co T3 tN CO -+ m , r^~ t^. O "ttN co« X X_ CO O O M ■+ O tN x_ 4 g's 0* r^o" coo" ■*• CO 2 E NN» to -4-00 O i- t^. c i^.Tj-tNvo i-o M X rf- co tN in co O ~i X qj ti •tOOOM NN-tN °°. a c 5 to O _. tN"o"x" <-Too" M Ox" t^ x co iox ox mo 1 NX O tNX m O t^ vO c R e y — -t- -1-x «» mo m 1- rt IN "1 — tN H u u. rt - > tfl h O t^X O O — tN CO TTTTZZZZ 00 x x x r 5 I48 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR > 10 On 10 NO IO 10 CO NO co C5 -t CN • CN t~; •"i. ' 00 £ 00 "*> ! in N '. ', '. tN ON ^ 10 00 ON IO O NO 00 CO On NO >h r^. t^ On t^ 1^- O CN 10 O cjn cn 8 ^ OS hH t^ O" NO_ -)-... o_ 00" ON i-M tN CM On On t^ no ; ; ; 00 CN CO « CO co m tN On 1^ O t^ _ M ITS O On -1- 00 t» On NO O CO co CN NO IO O CO § 0" O -5? ON On CN r^ 0" : : : CO On ^ ~ - t^ t^ 00 t^ 00 ^ sD t^. m (-1 t^. ti- • • • t-» 8 8 M - CN* CO CN NO* cS : : : in ON CO ■<*■ rT CN •<+ CO Cn! t-». On M co °°- °1 1-1 no" r-" cn" CO cn" CN t^ CN CN c- CN 00 ir t^ tN 00 t^ O 00 On O u- On <■<- »t C\ CO t> ■* O NO rf r i O On § O" On 0*.nO NO* ■* M : : : CN 00 rC cn ^ CN O ON t^ «-> 00 10 c NO rJ-0_ »H NO_ O^ r^ as IT t~>. ,_r IN 4 n h M in HH CM H O co CN Tf O ON rf IO O NO •* NO Cn! 00 VO tv. IH 00 l-H O t^ ON m cOnO_ o* vo tN. 5 ih IO 00 § 0" ON I^no" Ov CO 00 NO' CN O O VO 00 ON lOO CO O O On CO CO O IO >* M tN NO Tf i^ e» CO OI^ O M p-T of ON w* 1-1 CO w <* CO r^ On NO NO 00 On O CN (3n O CN 00 ■* NO NO ■* O n CN VO 11 O 00 CO 00 q_ cn CO lO >0 o_ r^ § co On CO M O CO VO CO O " O 00 00 Sh no CO co 00 IO CN t^ O O O CO 10 Tf 00 e» CO rf ON t>. 0_ CN ■* HH tN t-t M 10 ^ co CO CO NO O l^ 00 h-t On no OO IO NO « - co >-<_ in N ON k" ■4- NO NO 00 ^ : On NO tT . 1-1 M m 1- ;.•<*■ cn rf 1-1 cn" ^ en .« eu c eu C c A '• 8 8 :x "O ft u O u • eu en in O a id 3 Oh eu 3 u en c u en eu a 3 cn en 3 " Cy Q, cture of arms, dinary expen my construct '0 c 'en Sit c "5 c >< "o ■*-> c be 3 pS 3 g « ction of H railways for leaf-toba nnlv s of leaf-toba poly bureau . . of bonds and 4. c/ 7 en en 0) 1* c s c 3 £*0 CO I- u rt K ° C n (0 c 'en cc X a nprov( ment onstru kaido apital mono xpense mono; rintine a rj c t c 2 L, htf «-. w 2 w W <-> u u W Oh EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANCE 149 s On 00 00 On M 00" vO* ri i/-j vO ro ro 00 ro o o "1- ro vO t^ Ov rO 00 t-» ^ - r^.00 -re 6 -r "■< to r^oo Oh S 00 O on n 00 00 00 t-^ ro» - -C r — 1 ~ t~ 5 ""> ^ ON 1/5 O 10 o On rO VO* "* (S ON vO ID « o UO r- i/".0~ 00 00 rO ON VO "■- 1 -. oi 1— O vO ON ►* N rO -to I^O p" •>*• 10 on M O >0 ~ ~ Ph b Tf • vO W ►"! ON ro • _ vo 10 . 10 t^ cs M vO n\3 c o rt (j o ana a S n d m o o o G U E 2"--3 « «■? a 5 £ o o ^ c.E o n CvC (/) O — <->-, C i_ _, - 80 •r. C 9 a <" rt v c a. ►> >< • r: N _ v u I- frfi* u nj <2 O 5 o-a u o 'i ^ - > • ~ CJ*— O g" U 3 IS C - td u eg w o " ^ tn rt i_ W U - "• o w r; 0- - - ^u; W 6 u - - -/ -' : ?£■ ai 150 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Table X. — Revenue for Post-bellum Enterprises and Annual Balance Interest on Compensation Fisc al War expense for return of Total Amount Balance yea r indemnity Liaotung Peninsula increase and decrease revenue expended Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen 1805 . . 74,143,054 44,907,499 93,624 119,144,177 78,957,165 40,187,012 1896 83,719,110 911.65-2 84,630,762 11,789,389 113,028,385 18Q7 . . 34,869,189 7,071,097 41,940,286 40,360,796 114,607,875 1898 . . 118,341,511 1,341,450 119,682,961 66,187,071 168,103,765 1899 311,277 311,277 82,636,90s 85,778,137 1900 661,313 661,313 31,240,140 55,i99,3io 1901 1,705.783" 1,705,783° 20,883,427 32,610,100 1902 155.337 s 155.337 s 13,866,937 18,587,826 1903 147,073 147,073 9.S14.215 9,220,684 1904 57,849 57,849 3.544.375 5,734.158 1905 154,009 154,009 1,709,797 4,178,370 To tal 311,072,864 44,907,499 8,888,224 364,868,587 360,690,217 4,178,370 B Decrease. Table XI. — Expenditures for Post-bellum Enterprises Redemption Extraordi- Amount transferred of Sino-Jap- anese War Estab- nary war expendi- Fiscal year expenses, and transfer Army expansion Naval expansion lishment of iron ture and expenses of perial house- hold and to Total to General foundry communi- Accounts cation funds Fund bureau Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen 1895... 78,957,165 78,957,165 1896. . . 7,588,356 4,043,729 157,304 11,789,389 1897.. - 16,193.396 20,633,455 383.156 3,150,789 40,360,796 1898.. . 12,000,000° 8,932,554 25. 151. 519 39,302 63.696 20,000, 000 b 66,187,071 1899.. • 6,053,980 26,582,925 50,000,000° 82,636,905 1900. . . 8,121,594 23,118,546 31,240,140 1901. . . 5,346,896 15,536,531 20,883,427 1902. . . 3,083,189 10,783,748 13.866,937 1903.. 1,258,552 8,255,663 9. 514. 215 1904.. . 94.431 3,449,944 3,544,375 1905.. ■ 108,761 1,601,036 1,709,797 Total 90,957.165 56,781,709 139,157.096 579.762 3,214,485 70,000,000 360,690,217 • General Accounts Fund. b Imperial Household. Various Funds. EFFECTS OX PUBLIC FINANI E LSI X C t"« "". r i — ""- Z 'i — ~t Z" 3 (OO tC V) !* 3 W h h ci N (O^IONC 'i "". o o « — 3 t/5 -r c o JO tn C -t ". 1^ ir. I — ~ z- m >o OH^ntono H I - "~- z - PL, M M _ _ c) C3 •*• \n lO og w ?? a Ft) bt C "". "X-. l^sC "tlOn — N -f *u > 3 - O M — 00 f.X -t-tir./. Z (A o « = _ _ _ n c f. -tif. nc £ 3 H > .3 "o tn O fj "1- 1~» C^ — Cjvfi C IO C N vC C IOC 10^0 C -ti> c "5 - C N £ NO 00 - -r I - ix-. C o E u HHHNN CI bo rt ha O tn cj aj 3 O ONflOMf.'tNl''. CtO V, u o 4i/)m f*; ■" nnc c — W £5 i- •- >- c*> u s £ F T3 to O fit^vO — i-i -t-i^i-i i/;n 3 C — ^ n r > ~s. — N c -I- ** - c f- 3 « — — -t f, -t n : q c>xio o o o « = _~ N- " 5 rt H •> ir= = - (/i C -t^NO^I^T^fCO "5 ,o 3 - <-i CMO0C <-i O O C> O - - f| - N fl Tf 1^00 OOO "Z> u U " 3 o 9. 2 F T3 tuO c -+ c iam moi^o o o £ 3 rt O C - ''ivCOC - Nf, +IO u 3 O « = — O jd in o C f, ir-C " i-/ tOC t*i*C — — -t- C r i 3 CI mhhm N NN f)TT* 2 U ^5 3 O U (/) Q — M C •f^'tl'I^O O c o m o m o i — c c — -i- X w '1 - ri P| f| N n o , , t r , t > j - - r CHAPTER III EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET At the time of the Sino- Japanese War, our economic world bore the burden of war expenses amounting to about 236 million yen and met the issue of 100 million yen of war bonds. Such an enormous bond issue — and during war time too — had never been heard of before in Japanese history. So the government was careful not to burden the people too heavily, and by employing the Bank of Japan devised a suitable and effective financial policy whereby financial circles were enabled to pass quite tranquilly through the war. When diplomatic negotiations between Japan and China assumed a serious aspect, in June, 1894, financiers and econ- omists entertained grave anxiety. To understand the situa- tion we must realize that the financial policy of the government at that time was to prevent stagnation in the circulation of capital by restricting the construction of railways. So the Bank of Japan raised the loan interest rate on June 18, 1894, from 1.9 sen per diem (6.935 per cent per annum), which had been the rate in force from February 8, 1894, to 2 sen per diem (7.3 per cent per annum). The economic world was struck with terror; for, be it remembered, war with a foreign country was something of which the people of Japan had only read in books on history and of which they had not had the least direct personal experience. They were profoundly disturbed by the idea of crossing arms with China — a great nation hoary with age — and feared they knew not what great economic convulsion. The banks throughout the country called in their capital, restricted their loans, and were anxious only to protect themselves; the industrial world, expecting a decrease in the demand for goods during the war, restricted production; the people turned their attention altogether to economy, and commerce shrank; then, again, the Chinese residing in Japan, fearing that as a result of the opening of 152 EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MAKKI-.I 153 hostilities paper currency might greatly fall in price, would not accept anything but silver in payment, and demanded a premium of i\ per cent on paper currency — so great was the apprehension felt by economic circles ! But when the war began and arms were actually crossed between Japan and China, the Imperial Japanese Army at once won a great victory and there was strong confidence in the minds of the people that the final outcome would be favorable to Japan. This restored confidence in the money market, which then became very firm. When the war bonds were issued, the people were moved by patriotism and the re- sult of the popular subscriptions to the bonds was very good. The interest rate was very low, only 5 per cent, and this had a great effect in quieting the market, because at that time financiers had an idea that if the interest rate on the bonds was very high, general interest rates would become high also. As had been explained before, the whole financial world was seriously shaken up at the commencement of this inter- national war and at the same time the people in general were deeply influenced toward economy, so that with the exception of the articles of daily necessity and war materials, the de- mand for merchandise decreased considerably. Then again, owing to the dislocation of land and water transportation facilities on account of the pressing need of transporting troops and war materials, the accumulation and disposition of commercial articles was hindered and consequently the operation of capital was affected seriously. The prices of daily necessities and also of war materials rose at the place- < >1 consumption. So commerce experienced great depression and the demand for industrial capital decreased greatly. How- ever, foreign vessels were chartered, and by this means the defect in water transportation facilities was remedied and the circulation of money greatly facilitated. These steps helped somewhat in restoring commercial prosperity. Furthermore, as regards foreign trade, it was at first ex- pected that trade with China and Korea would be most seriously affected. But the government devised various 154 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR means of relief for the China trade, and furnished the needed financial facilities, so that the dislocation of trade proved to be only temporary. After our country had secured control of the sea, especially, the China trade did not suffer seriously. As for trade with Korea, no bad effects from the war were felt there, either, after navigation was made safe. The American route was from the beginning perfectly safe and European trade suffered no ill effects at all. Both routes being free from disturbance, a tendency toward constantly increasing development was shown. While there was thus no particular disturbance to com- merce either at home or abroad, the currency, affected by the war expenditures, was gradually inflated, as is shown in Table I at the end of this chapter. 1 Thus on the restoration of peace (April 30, 1895), compared with conditions at the beginning of the war (June 30, 1894) there was an increase of about 44 million yen and on December 31, 1895, of about 85 million yen. This inflation of the currency was caused by an increase in the issue of coins and paper currency and by the payments made from the Treasury. These were results of the war expenditure, for this expenditure of about 200 million yen was made with various kinds of specie, while the government, as one of its financial measures during war time, spent the money at home as much as possible, so that naturally coin and paper currency increased consider- ably. The following table will show the facts as to the in- crease of convertible notes out of paper money. Date January 31, 1894 June 30, 1894 December 31,1 894 January 31, 1895 April 30, 1895 December 31, 1895 Comparison with J u ne 30, 1 894 : December 31, 1894 December 31, 1895 Bank-note Specie Reserve Extra limit issue reserve securities issue Yen Yen Yen Yen 147,372,199 141.736,358 149,813,700 142,756,092 132,839,984 180,336,815 84,515,404 79,632,988 81,718,291 80,924,075 68,532,320 60,370,797 62,856,795 62,103,370 68,095,409 61,832,017 64,307,664 119,966,018 4.197.549 55.083,148 8.077.342 s 38,600,457" 2,085,303" I9,262,i9i b 5.992,039" 57,862,648" 5,499,640" 56,385,239" 1 Post, p. 196. » Increase. b Decrease. Reserve power of issue Yen 299,973 1,302,091 2,547,265 7,618 EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET 1 55 Judging from the foregoing table, we find the specie re- serve was not greatly affected during the war. Even in the securities reserve there was a certain amount of reserve strength of issue left, so that the financial condition for war time was excellent. After the war the specie reserve rather decreased, and the extra-limit issue was effected; for the effect produced on the securities resent issue during this period was due to the increase or decrease of the specie re- serve as the case might be. The decrease of an enormous amount of specie reserve after the restoration of peace was altogether due to (i) the payments in silver made for war expenses, (2) the paying out of convertible notes, as these were especially demanded by the Chinese merchants, and (3) the unfavorable balance of foreign trade. Aside from these fad s, the general condition, as to deposits and loans, of the Bank of Japan and the private banks, as well as the interest rate, remained normal, as we shall explain later; so that except for the precautionary attitude which was taken during war time there was nothing particularly noteworthy in the situation. Thus we see that during the war finances were in an un- usually normal condition. To be sure, an enormous amount of money was spent for the war without any return and 200,- 000 men were called out of productive industries to the front, thereby restricting the productive power of the nation and causing a change in the industrial order, so that it was im- possible to prevent economic changes later, the seeds of which were indeed germinating during the war. Nevertheless it is a fact that conditions similar to those of peace were maintained during war time. The following may 1 »e gr\ en as the principal reasons why this was possible: (1) The war itself was a stimulus to the mind- of the people, and a potent cause in producing thoughtful, conservative action. We have noted at first how excessive precautions were taken, how the money market at once became tight, demand for capital decreased, owing to fears as tol he financial future, and idle capital increased, because owing to the pre- cautions of business men lucrative ways of disposing of it I56 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE S1NO-JAPANESE WAR could not be found. All these things helped to prevent the expected panic in the money market. In other words, money circulation shrank not from real necessity but for psy- chological reasons. (2) The financial policy of the government was duly carried out, since (a) stagnation of capital for railway enter- prises was prevented, (b) interest on bonds was lowered, (c) special attention was paid to the collection and circulation of the funds secured from bonds, (d) suitable steps were taken for facilitating commercial transactions. (3) The activity of the Bank of Japan was altogether be- yond that necessitated by the consideration of immediate profits for herself, having for its object the securing of the wel- fare of the nation. Loans were restricted or bonds redeemed and at the same time the fund secured by bond issues was fur- nished to the people for their use, and the government was supplied with capital as loans to meet the urgent need of war. On the other hand, the convertible notes were controlled and the interest rate was preserved from fluctuation. (4) Besides the Bank of Japan, the influential banks of Tokyo, Osaka and other cities, in order to facilitate the circulation of money in war time, cooperated with the Central Bank in facilitating the issue of bonds, or subscribed for the bonds themselves and restricted their loans, in order to pre- vent the equilibrium of financial circles from being disturbed. (5) The nation expected that, as a result of repeated success at the front, the final victory would be with Japan. The minds of business men were set at ease and there was no further anxiety entertained as to money circulation for the future. These various reasons combined to quiet the money market in time of war. But this was only a temporary phenomenon. As has been said, the extraordinary financial conditions after the war were being germinated during the war. These conditions led to frequent fluctuations after the war which were only relieved just before the Russo-Japanese conflict. \\ lien the Sino- Japanese War, the only international war EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET I 57 Japan had waged since the Restoration, ended in a glorious victory for Japan, and an enormous indemnity was obtained and the Liaotung Peninsula and Formosa were ceded to us, the Japanese nation first became conscious of her real strength, and various important national movements then had their inception. In the world of thought, the idea of "Japanism," as it was called, was cherished; in the economic world the former pessimism gave place to optimism; while an incn in extravagance together with the gendering of a spirit of enterprise were the results of these national movements. But before this stimulation produced any substantial re- sults, the interference of the European Powers in the peace negotiations with China came suddenly, dealing a severe blow to the nation. The optimism which had just been expanding was altogether subdued. We shall not take the time or trouble to describe this interference, as it is already a fact well known to the world. Just how it enraged our nation may be realized by recalling the fact that the Nihon, a daily newspaper edited by Dr. Yujiro Miyake, a noted critic, reported the news of the return of the Liaotung Penin- sula to the people by issuing an extra headed with these words "Urgent Imperial Message has been issued." "Who that has red blood in his veins will not read it with tears?" And the forty million people affected did indeed look at this unjust interference with bloody tears. The Taiyo, a political review, under the title of "Patient, Watch- ful Waiting," said: "We must repay the good will of the Three Powers, as we are not a nation who would forget the favors of others." Thus the so-called "Patient, Watchful Waiting" and the " Ten- Years' Plan," became the watchwords of the time and gave the people the opportunity to reflect. These watchwords were in keeping with the national move- ment which was started by the war and led to the realization of the plan of a big army and navy and of replenishing the nation's wealth; thus a heavy burden was laid upon the pe< »ple owing to the expanded financial program of the government. However, the depression in economic circles caused by the I58 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR ret recession of the Liaotung Peninsula did not last long. The national self-realization, which resulted from the victory, materialized in the world of thought as " Japanism," while in the economic world a national movement was also inaugu- rated. So, although the spirit of the nation was sadly de- pressed at first because of the return of the Liaotung Peninsula, in an incredibly short time confidence was restored, as the people were buoyed up by the expectation of a large indemnity to be received from China, and the spirit of enterprise was born again. At this opportune time the Bank of Japan instituted the policy of encouraging enterprises by loosening its purse, so that the spirit of enterprise became widespread, its heartening influence being in inverse ratio to the de- pression caused by the return of the Liaotung Peninsula. Consequently, the tendency to frugality which was favored during the war was very generally superseded by extrava- gance, prices rose, — though this was not the only cause, — foreign trade showed an excess of imports over exports, and the business world experienced a complete change. Although, as we have stated before, the "Ten- Years' Plan" was a serious proposition, considering the national strength at the time, yet it was easily executed on account of the rising spirit of the nation ; and this enterprising spirit rose as the result of the aforementioned national movement in the economic world. But as during the war industrial capital had been absorbed in war expenditure, and after the war, in the various enterprises undertaken by government and people, capital became suddenly static. Then, besides, the greater part of the indemnity received from China was spent for unproduc- tive purposes, which, so far from helping capitalists, caused the evils which naturally accompany the inflation of currency. Moreover, the securities reserve note issue of the Bank of Japan was increased more and more. The result was the encouragement of a spirit of extravagance, and a rise in prices, which placed various difficulties in the way of materializing the enterprising spirit of the time, and even made political trouble. The ministry was changed several times. Conse- EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARK! I 1 59 quently the national movement for progressive enterprises whieh arose after the war was cheeked, and the high spirits of the nation were depressed, and finally the finan< ial distress experienced after the war led to a slight panic in 1899. This was not perfectly relieved, and another panic occurred in 1901. The national movement also, which had promised great things at the close of the war, was kept from expanding, and in this condition the nation had to meet the Russo-J a] tanese War. The financial ups and downs during the Sino-Japanese War and ten years thereafter have been briefly explained. We shall now proceed to set forth financial conditions during that time by taking up the most important points in connection therewith. Reform of the Currency System Japan established the gold standard monetary system by Law No. 16, promulgated on March 26, 1897. The monetary system of our country prior to this time had been based upon the bimetallic system established by the Tokugawa Shogunate in the sixth year of Keicho, 1 601, and maintained for 260 years or until the period of the Restoration of Meiji. But whenever financial distress occurred the metallic money was reminted, and except during the reform of the Kyoho period, the weight of the coins was reduced and the quality debased, so that the currency system in this way destroyed itself. In feudal times some anion- the Daimios coined moneys with their own imprints thereon and issued notes to circulate- only in their own territory, and there were 1,600 or more different kinds of notes in circulation. In short, in the lasl days of the Tokugawa Shogunate our mone- tary system was at the extreme height of disorder and com- plexity. The government attempted to readjust matters in the early part of the Meiji era. In May, 1871, a new currency law- was promulgated, thereby laying the basis for the gold-stand- ard system. According to this law, the yen, containing t.5 grams of pure gold about 900 and i| grams of alloy was l6o ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR made the unit of currency. There was besides this system, another with a trade silver yen, the same in quality and weight as the Mexican silver dollar current in the Orient as the unit of trade currency. Now the trade silver yen was circulated only within open ports. But at that time, inconvertible notes were issued in our country, so that specie flowed out in a great stream, and it was felt that to maintain a gold standard system among silver countries in the Orient was a very difficult task. So in May, 1878, Laws Nos. 12 and 13 were issued, whereby the trade silver yen was ordered for general circulation at home, in paying taxes, and for pub- lic and private transactions. From that time, Japan became a bimetallic country. The government, owing to the civil war and other momen- tous events in the early part of Meiji, found it difficult to meet all its needs by means of Treasury revenue alone. So it was obliged to issue the following varieties of notes in order to secure temporary relief : Date of Issue Total Amount of Issue Kinds (1) Dajokwan Notes (Cabinet) May 15, 1868-Dec. 31, 1869. . (2) Mimbusho Notes (Notes is- sued by Dept. of People) Sept. 17, 1869-Oct. 31, 1870 (3) Convertible Notes by Finance Department, Oct. 12, 1871- Feb. 28, 1872.' 48,000,000 ryo 7,500,000 ryo (At first it was in- tended to redeem the Dajokwan notes of small denomina- tions with these notes.) 6,800,000 10 ryo, 5 ryo, 1 ryo,i bu, 1 shu. 2 bu, 1 bu, 2 shu, 1 shu. (4) Convertible Notesby Colonial Department, Jan. 14, 1872- Mar. 31, 1872 2,500,000 10 yen, 5 yen, I yen. 10 yen, 5 yen, 1 yen, 50 sen, 20 sen, \osen. But when the daimiate system was abolished and the pre- fectural system was established in 1871, the notes issued by different daimiates had to be taken over by the central government ; thus it was necessary to increase the notes of the EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET l6l central government to aid in this adjustment, and finally new government notes were issued. The inconvertible notes suddenly increased to an enormous amount. According to the proclamation of December 27, 1871, concerning the issue of new notes, these notes were to be circulated in exchange for the notes of different daimiates. As a result, the former became inconvertible notes. Then, when the Civil War of 1877 broke out in the southwest, the government was obliged to issue notes to the amount of 27 million yen temporarily in order to meet the war expenses. As the notes in circulation exceeded the need of the economic world, there was a sudden rise in the prices of commodities. Furthermore, by Decree No. 104, issued in August, 1876, the law governing national banks (Law No. 349, November 15, 1872) was revised. The regulations allowing the national banks to issue bank notes with 6 per cent bonds redeemable in gold notes as security 1 were revised, so that bonds bearing 4 per cent intercut were allowed to be used as security. The maximum total issue of bank notes was fixed at 34 million yen. After that, these bank notes were issued in large amounts. But as they were convertible with the currency then in circulation, namely, government paper money, the prices of the notes fell con- siderably, the prices of commodities rose, the specie flowed out, the imports exceeded the exports, and farmers became extravagant in their expenditures. The evil effects were very serious and one who reviews the history of that period can not but be horrified thereby. In consequence the government made strenuous efforts to revise the currency system, on the one hand redeeming tin- notes, and, after the establishment of the Bank of Japan in June, 1882, ordering that bank to issue convertible silver banknotes from May, 1885; and on the other hand, endeavor- ing to accumulate specie reserve, thereby gradually restoring the credit of the government notes. The market value of the notes increased accordingly, and at the end of 1885 the 1 These were authorized for the purpose of replacing the government notes then in circulation. [62 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR difference between silver and the notes nearly vanished. So from January I, 1886 (according to Decree No. 14, issued June 6, 1885) government notes could be converted into silver at par. In addition, the plan of redeeming the national hank notes was also established by Decree No. 14, issued in 1883, and thus our country became a true silver standard country. Previous to this, from about 1871, the production of silver all over the world increased and the price of silver showed signs of declining. When Germany, in 1873, es- tablished the gold-standard system by utilizing the indemnity received as a result of the Franco-Prussian War and began to dispose of the silver in her possession, the price of silver fell still more. Then when the United States of America, the Latin-Alliance nations, and other countries adopted the gold-standard system, and restricted or stopped the minting of silver coins, thus initiating the policy of excluding silver and gathering in gold, the price of silver fell considerably lower. In 1876, the ratio between gold and silver, in price, was on an average 1 to 17.88. Whereupon the silver- producing countries and those which possessed silver began to discuss methods of maintaining the price of this metal. The United States of America was especially noteworthy, as in 1878 she passed the Brand Law, whereby silver was purchased and minted, and in 1890 the Sherman Law, which extended the scope of the former statute. But both failed to prevent the steady fall in the price of silver. Consequently, Austria- Hungary, in 1892, changed her monetary system, adopting the gold standard, and in 1893 the United States of America revoked the Sherman Law. India also abolished the free coinage of silver. Other countries likewise ceased using silver for coins. As a result, in 1894 the ratio between gold and silver became on an average 1 to 32.56. After this explanation, it is not necessary to show in detail how Japan, which was virtually a silver-standard country, was affected. On the one hand, following the fall in the price of silver, the exports of our country increased and the prices of commodities rose, so that agricultural, industrial and EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 163 commercial circles were benefited and became quite prosper- ous; but on the other hand, the foreign exchange rate was constantly fluctuating so that those engaged in foreign trade were in danger of monetary losses and could not transact business with the certainty as to profits or losses previously assured, but had to wait idly until the fluctuations in the exchange rate became a little less serious or were obliged to venture forth depending only upon luck. Consequently, transactions became speculative and business dealings with gold-standard countries assumed a state of impasse, which in turn produced an unfavorable result upon the money market. Below we indicate the tendencies of the exchange rates in London, Paris and Berlin: Rates of Exchange in London, Paris and Berlin Year London Pa ris Berlin Highest Lowest Highest Lowest I tighest Lowest s. d. 5. d. /• /• VI. m. 1886. 3.04.04 3.00.13 4.21 3-79 3 35 3 03 1887. 3.03.80 301. 32 4.19 3 93 3-34 3 13 1888. 3.01.58 3 00.05 3-95 3 79 3-16 3.01 1889. 3.02.52 3.00.36 4 03 3 84 3 22 3 06 1890. 3.09.08 3.01 . 10 4-73 3 92 3-78 3 i- 1891. 30519 3.01.32 4-33 3 93 3 \" 3 15 1892. 300. 51 2.08.64 3 84 3 43 3 08 2 75 i«93- 2.08.73 2.03.87 3-44 2 92 ^■77 2 36 1894. 2.03.50 1 . 1 1 . 50 2.87 2 45 2 31 i«95- 2.02.88 1. 11. 13 2.83 2 43 - -7 1 .96 For these reasons, the Japanese Government planned to change the silver-standard system into the gold standard, and in accordance with Imperial Ordinance No. 113, issued on October 14, 1893, appointed a committee to investigate the currency system and to learn the cause of the fluctuation in the prices of gold and silver; also whether there was need of reforming the currency system of our country, because of Un- economic effects which the fluctuation in the prices of gold and silver produced in Japan, and if their was such nerd, what system should be adopted. The committee by a ma- jority vote decided to adopl the gold-standard system. 1 64 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR But the reform could not be accomplished by means of a set of laws. A large amount of gold reserve was needed. From 1 87 1 until the gold standard was established, the total amount of silver issued was on its face value 165,133,710 yen. It was not an easy matter to accumulate a gold reserve suffi- cient to convert this amount of silver into gold, and it was necessary to wait for a favorable opportunity. However, an agreement was finally reached whereby the war indemnity of the Sino-Japanese War, which was to have been received in Kuping taels, was received in British gold in London. With this amount the gold-standard system was established. In discussing the proposition of establishing the gold- standard system, some suggested that it would be advan- tageous to plan the development of trade with gold-standard countries in view of the fall in the price of silver, or objected that if Japan alone should adopt the gold-standard system while various other countries in the Orient were silver-stand- ard countries, she would encounter serious obstacles in carrying on trade with those countries; it was also said that, as the production of gold in our country is too small for our needs, it would be difficult to maintain the gold-standard system permanently, and that when the large amount of silver exported abroad should be reimported into Japan, the nation would meet with great losses. In spite of all these objections, the government decided to adopt the gold-stand- ard system. While the foregoing were the alleged reasons for making this change, there was still another reason, namely, the money market conditions of that time; for it is plain now that if silver fell, the investment of capital by gold-standard countries in Japan, which was still a silver country, would decrease, and the capital already invested would be recalled. This was not clearly seen at the time, since our finances had received bad effects from the post-bellum undertakings and showed signs of abnormality, resulting in the contraction of the money circu- lation and the falling of prices of shares in the stock market. Thus the opinion came to prevail in financial circles that if the EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 165 gold-standard system were adopted at that time the obstacles between Japan and the gold-standard countries would be removed and the cheap capital of countries more advanced commercially would at once be invested here; for this reason there were not a few who favored the gold-standard system. Accordingly the bill for currency reform was passed by both houses immediately, and by Law No. 16, issued March 26, 1897, the new system was put into operation. Thus from October 1 of the same year, Japan became a gold-standard country. That the financial world thus desired to see the gold- standard system established because of the conditions which existed at that time may be gathered from the fact that when the news was circulated in the stock market, securities rose in price. A few examples are cited below : Effect of Currency Reform Bill on Stock Exchange N. Y. K. Tanko Railway Sanyo Railway Kanega- fuchi Spinning Tokyo Stock Exchange Rumor of Bill being introduced: Previous day On the day Rise Yen 78.10 79 -50 1 .40 Yen 87.70 89.80 1 . 10 Yen 53 90 55 10 1 .20 Yen 60.00 61 .00 1 .00 Yen 369-50 376.00 650 Introduction in House of Commons: Feb. 26 March I Rise 79-50 81 .30 1 .80 98.80 99.80 1 on 55 10 56.40 1 -30 61 .40 62.00 0.60 •i 00 386.00 10.00 Approved by Special Committee of the 1 louse: Previous day March 6 Rise 7570 77 30 1 60 95.80 97 -30 1 50 55 00 55 20 0.20 6i .60 (>2 . IO O.5O 369 9 1 ;,:<>. 00 9 50 Passed by the House: Previous day March 12 Fluctuation 76.90 76.60 . 30 97-50 98. ID O.6O 55 00 55.60 0.60 61 .10 386.00 Passed by Peers: Previous day March 23 Fluctuation 76.90 76.60 030 99 30 101 . 10 1.80 55 30 55-70 .40 62.10 62. 10 385.00 402 .00 17.00 166 economic effects of the sino-japanese avar Expansion of Issue Capacity of Convertible Notes The revised law governing the issue of convertible bank notes issued in March, 1899, raised the amount of the securi- ties reserve issue from 85 million yen to 120 million yen. This was due to the fact that the government believed the in- creasing stringency of the money market indicated a shortage of capital or currency (bank notes), and previous to that period the bank notes were almost always issued in excess of the settled limitation. What, then, was the condition of the extra-limit issue of notes? Before we discuss this matter, we must describe the securities reserve issue of notes by the Bank of Japan, especially the history of the extra-limit issue. The Bank of Japan was established as a central bank on October 10, 1882, at the time when inconvertible notes (both government and bank notes) fell in price, in order to meet the emergency, in accordance with Decree No. 32, issued on June 27, 1882, setting forth the purpose of the bank. Beginning from September 8, 1886, the bank's notes were issued, in accordance with Decree No. 18 of May 26, 1885, regulating the issue of convertible bank notes. At first the bank was required to keep only a reasonable amount of reserve specie to redeem the bank notes issued. 1 The Minister of Finance occasionally suggested the amount of notes to be issued, and the reserve for the exchange was at first limited to specie. But later the government notes and bank notes were constantly being adjusted, so that at the end of June, 1889, the amount of government notes on hand was 49,337,248 yen, and of bank notes 28,059,486 yen. Compar- ing these figures with the highest amounts of the various notes in circulation, we see what an extraordinary amount of redemption had been effected. As there were 49,177,864 yen worth of notes on hand on the last day of June, 1888, there was after all a decrease of 43,- 582,880 yen. Consequently, the currency decreased con- siderably in amount. So the government firmly established 1 Article 2 of the same decree. EFFECTS ON Till-; MONEY MARKET Redemption of Bank Notes 167 Not< s Government notes. . National bank notes. Total amount of vari- ous notes Date Feb. 28, 1878 Feb. 28, 1879 Jan. 31, 1880 1 [ighest amounts of | Amount various notesjune 30, 18 in circulation Yen 141,274,862 28,347,876 i7o.i57.477 Yen 49.337.248 28,059,486 77.396.733 Decrease, June 30, (888 compared Yen 9i.937.6i5 288,390 92,760,744 the system of conversion and in addition decided that the time to do away altogether with the former currency system had now come. So the laws governing the issue for the conversion of the convertible bank notes were revised. While in principle issuing bank notes with gold and silver specie or gold and silver bullion as a reserve (that is, an issue based upon the specie reserve), the Bank of Japan was allowed at the same time to issue bank notes to the maximum limit of 70 million yen with government or other reliable securities or commercial documents as a guarantee. 1 In case of need the bank was permitted to increase the bank notes according to the market conditions, and to issue notes with the foregoing securities as a guarantee by paying to the government a tax on the issue at a rate of over 5 per cent per annum <>n the amount of the issue, after the permit of the Minister of Finance had been obtained. 2 This was based upon a lesson learnt from the principle of indirect restriction (Konzinsen- tierung) or the elasticity method of note issue followed by the Imperial Bank of Germany, and the Bank of Japan per- formed thereafter an important service .1- .1 steadier of the money market and the supplier of capital. Then, on March 3, 1890, for the first time there was 300,000 yen worth of the extra-limit issue. The highest amount was 500,000 yen, between March 10 and April 1. This was due to the fact that at that time, owing to the rise in the price of rice, the 1 Of this amount, 27 million yen was issued gradually, with the amount of the redempl ion ol the nal tonal bank notes since January 1 . 1889, .1- the limit. 1 This was the securitii - rea rve issue. [68 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR adverse balance of foreign trade, the reactionary influence on the rise of the enterprising spirit, and other causes, the money market showed the prevalence of abnormal conditions. But the government construed this fact as indicating that as a re- sult of the spirit of enterprise which had sprung up since 1887, various enterprises would develop rapidly, foreign trade would also be extended and the demand for the bank notes in circulation in the economic world of Japan would increase. So at length by Law No. 34, issued May 16, 1890, the amount of the securities reserve issue was increased from 70 million yen to 85 million yen. This was the opening wedge in the extension of the securities reserve issue, which we are to discuss here. The government, influenced by the experience of some nine years thereafter, ultimately increased the amount to 120 million yen. Let us describe the actual occurrences of these years. A reaction following the relaxing of the money market since 1 891 was shown in the latter half of 1893. Foreign trade showed an adverse balance. Furthermore, on the breaking out of the Sino- Japanese War, the second extra- limit issue took place. From December 29, 1894 (3> 2 7 2 >7 21 yen), to January 12, 1895, the highest amount was 4,197,549 yen at the end of December, 1894, and the average amount was 2,211,054 y en - In April, 1895, a peace treaty with China was formulated. But owing to the return of the Liaotung Peninsula the people of Japan were downcast and the economic world greatly depressed. But as a result of the third extra-limit issue, on May 28, for the purpose of obtaining a loan for the govern- ment, and also because the Bank of Japan had instituted the policy of reviving finances by lowering the interest rate on loans, this extra-limit issue was continued from the end of May, 1905 (i,993,433 yen), to May 19, 1906; at the end of 1905 the amount reached 55,083,147 yen, the average amount throughout this period being 29,100,731 yen. This was an enormous amount, indeed. As the extra-limit issue of that time was due to the loans by the government, when the regu- EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 169 lations as to the disposal of deposits of the indemnity were established in May, 1896, this extra-limit issue was discon- tinued. Then, in the latter half of 1897, the reaction from the postbellum spirit of enterprise, the rise in the prices of commodities, and the adverse balance of foreign trade became both causes and effects in themselves, so that from July 24, 1893 (455,306 yen) until September 14, 1898, extra-limit issues were sent out four times, with a maximum amount of 47,312,- 657 yen at the end of 1897, and an average of 25,044485 yen. The reason for the withdrawal of the extra-limit issue was that the government had purchased the war and consolidat- ing bonds from April, 1898, and the money market had relaxed, and also that the government, in order to pay for the purchase of the bonds with the money borrowed on the indemnity de- posits, had returned the convertible notes of the extra-limit issue which had been borrowed from the Bank of Japan. In short, the extra-limit issue of the securities reserve was trans- formed apparently into the specie reserve convertible notes. But from October 26, 1898, especially from December 16, until February 21, 1899, an extra-limit issue of notes was again sent forth several times in succession, with a maximum amount of 24,016,568 yen at the end of December, 1898, and an average of 3,287,195 yen on the first occasion (from October 26 to November 7), 1,454,144 yen on the second occasion (from November 27 to December 1), and 8,254,165 yen on the last occasion (from December 16 to February 21, 1899). We shall briefly present below the average and the maximum amounts of extra-limit issues since the securities reserve issue was increased to 85 million yen: 1 titration Average Maximum Dec 29 1894— [an 12 1895 Yen 22,11 1,054 29,100,731 25.044.4 3.287,195 1.45L' tt : ,165 Yen 4.10; May 31 1895-May 19 1896 55.083,147 July 24 1897— Sept 14 1898 47.312,65; Oct 26 1 898-Nov 7 1 898 8,110,818 Nov 27 1898-Dec 1 1898 1,667 Dec 16 1 898— I* i-1 > 21 1899 24,016.- 14,875,296 170 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR That the actual results of the extra-limit issue were as described above is proved by the fact that the government and people of Japan raised the amount of the legal guar- antee reserve issue from 85 million yen to 120 million yen. The relation between the amount of the legal guarantee reserve issue and the demand for capital by the financiers of any nation is so well known to economists that there is no use of enlarging upon it here. But if we reflect a little we shall see that the extra-limit issue only signifies that the amount of the bank note issue has exceeded the limit estab- lished by law, whereas the so-called legal limit is not the limit of the first instance, but one based upon a fluctuating specie reserve issue. Hence it is not proper to judge the demand for capital in the economic circles of a country by this fact alone. We should observe also the specie, the guarantee reserve issue, and the total amount of the issue. Then, again, the legal extension of the amount of guarantee reserve issue permitted has given the Bank of Japan considerable power to supply capital, and as she would not be likely to neglect this opportunity to benefit herself, and as the eco- nomic world would eagerly appropriate this supply of cheap money, the currency in circulation would greatly increase and its effect upon general economic conditions in the country would not be slight. Accordingly, the discussion of the pro- priety of extending the issue would be a link in the discus- sion of post-bellum economy. Table II at the end of this chapter 1 shows the amount of bank note issues since 1894, when the extra-limit issue first appeared, and Table III 2 shows the increase and decrease compared with 1893. As shown in the foregoing tables, the bank note issues rapidly increased during this time. But there is one thing to be noted, namely, that during the foregoing period the con- vertible notes of the Bank of Japan were not the only paper currency issued. So we must consider the entire volume of paper currency in circulation during this period. 1 Post, p. 197. * Post, p. 198. EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET Paper Money in Circulation, i 893-1 899 171 At end of year 1893 1894 189s 1896 1897 1898 1899 (Feb.) 1899 (Dec.) Total. . . Government notes Yen 16,407,000 13.404.547 11,129,224 9.376,172 7,451,09s 5,411.726 5.293.724 4.125.783 72,599.274 National bank notes Yen 22,756,119 21.781,797 20,796,786 16,497.889 1.866,563 1,684,065 90.407. 94S Convertible notes of Bank of Japan Yen 148,663.128 149.813.700 180,336,815 198.313.896 226,319.058 I97.399.90i 181,218,176 250.562,040 1.532,626.714 Total Amount Comparison with 1893 Yen 187.826.247 185,000,044 212,262,825 224.i87.9S7 238.794.885 204,678,100 188,195.965 254.687.823 1.695.633.936 100. o 98. 5 113 o H9-4 127 . 1 109.0 100.2 I3S 6 From the foregoing tables, it will be seen that while the increase in the notes issued by the Bank of Japan was great, yet these notes, except when required by the natural demands of the economic world, were issued to replace the government notes and bank notes which were in process of gradual ad- justment or extinction, and that in reality the total volume of the paper currency rose and fell in turn without showing any very great permanent increase. Moreover, the extra-limit issue of the convertible notes of the Bank of Japan was effected in many instances when there was a decrease in specie. The extra-limit issues of May, 1895, and July, 1897. both coincided with the decrease in the specie reserve. But in financial circles there was always need of a certain fixed amount of convertible notes. In case the amount of the issue of convertible notes fell below what was necessary, be- cause of a decrease in the specie reserve, it may naturally be inferred that by some other method the guarantee reserve issue, for instance— the deficiency would be met, and that the cause of the increase on the guarantee reserve issue lay, aside from the government loans, in the increase in in- dustrial loans made to the people generally. That the loans made by the Bank of Japan increased extraordinarily is shown in Table IV at the cud of this chapter. 1 1 Post, p. I 172 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Extra-Limit Issues of Convertible Notes At end of Specie reserve Decrease compared with month's end, from standard Bank note issue Extradimit issue 1895 April May (June-Nov. omitted) Dec 1896 Jan Feb March April May (June-Dec. omitted) 1897 (J an. -May omitted) June July (Aug.-Nov. omitted) Dec 1898 Jan Feb Mar (April-July omitted) Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec Yen 68,532,320 66,199,000 60,370,797 54,890,176 54,589,146 55.347.oo2 55.574.499 106,308,649 119,437,064 109,780,678 98,261,473 91,568,364 83,626,224 74,651,152 88,498,228 91,307,480 88,468,720 90,180,017 89.570,239 Standard 2,333,320 8,161,523 13,642,144 13,943,174 13,185,318 12,957,821 37,776,329 a Standard 9,656,386 21,175,591 27,868,700 35,810,840 44,785,912 30,938,836 28,129,584 30,968,344 29,257,047 29,866,825 Yen 132,839,984 132,573,715 180,336,815 171,211,604 164,408,373 157,141,819 154,748,631 165,837,762 195,302,669 198,728,088 226,229,058 212,003,989 195,297,483 195,889,761 186,361,320 174,472,809 180,122,704 177,581,079 197,399,901 Yen 1,993,433 55,083,148 50,937,636 44,434,259 36,409,048 33,786,956 10,325,196 47,312,657 39,529,488 30,626,515 39.658,322 14,681,165 8,110,818 3,677,028 24,016,569 a Increase. The origin of the extra-limit issue and the increase in loans being as just stated, we see that the government considered the limit of the guarantee reserve issue too small; especially since, owing to the stringency of the money market at that time, commercial and industrial circles desired the legal limit of the issue to be extended and the powers of the Bank of Japan to be increased. Moved by this request, the govern- ment extended the legal limit by Law No. 55, issued March 9, 1898, and applied 15 million yen out of the 35 million yen increase to the relief of the domestic money market, thereby EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET 1 73 opening the way for high-class exchange transactions, the discounting of checks, and an increase in branch banks. At the same time, 20 million yen were applied to relieve the stringency of the money market and facilitate transactions with Europe, America and the Orient. The Yokohama Specie Bank was ordered to engage in the work of facilitating the China trade especially. But we believe it was a mistake, in view of existing condi- tions at that time, to extend the legal limit of the guarantee reserve issue merely because of the frequency of extra-limit issues, without first investigating what the reason was for the increase in convertible notes. We do not mean to argue at length as to the merit of the policy here. We only wish to make it clear how this procedure disturbed the money market after the war and created an unfavorable effect upon the national finances. For even if the amount of the guarantee reserve issue had been determined by law, it would not have bound economic circles; and even if the issue of notes should go beyond the legal limit, it would not menace the financial interests, so that the extension of the legal limit by 35 million yen as mentioned above had no practical significance at all. But the extension of the amount of issue exempted from taxation allowed the Bank of Japan has given that bank great power to furnish capital — such that if this power were employed wrongfully, bank notes would be al a premium and this would have serious effects upon finance. Then, again, our financiers and economists, drunk with tin ulnry <>i" vietory after the Sino-Japane>e War, were aboul to make great strides ahead when Japan was obliged t<> return the Liaotung Peninsula. The people suddenly bee, mie pessimistic. So the government adopted .1 liberal policy and ordered the Bank of Japan to lower the rate <>t' interest. 1 This was done in order to en< ourage the people, so that optimism might be gradually restored and the people realize that they need no longer remain depressed. They accordingly took courage 1 At that time the discount rate was ^ sen 1 tin per diem, that is 7.665 per cent, which was changed to I sen 9 nn per diem, thai is 6 935 per cent. IJ4 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR and became enthusiastic over post-bellum enterprises; the demand for capital for army and naval expansion and for the prosecution of said enterprises increased enormously, and finally a great financial panic occurred, as is mentioned later. Thus the sudden increase in capital after the war was due partly to the need of the government, but not a little to the deliberate policy of the government and the Central Bank. Consequently, the development of a sudden demand for capital as described heretofore can not be considered the result of a healthy development, or a natural evolution in the economic life of the people ; for in economic development there are true and false tendencies. That financial circles which have shown a tendency to great activity should suddenly shrink from advancing is a phenomenon to be observed only in a period of speculation and vainglory. The conditions in the financial circles of our country after the Sino- Japanese War were indeed such. Judged from these facts, the arguments advanced in favor of extending the amount of the guarantee reserve issue based upon the phenomena resulting from this false tendency may be considered as castles in the air, with great instability of foundation. They can not escape the criticism of inconsistency. As has been said, the extension of the amount of the guar- antee reserve issue can not properly be considered necessary, judging from the point of view of a dispassionate critic. On the contrary it poured oil on the prairie fire of the false phenomena of financial circles in order to cause an increase in the issue of convertible notes and may be considered as one cause of unsteady ing the money market. If we remember that the so-called extension of the issue by 35 million yen is 22 per cent of 158,517,000,000 yen, which was the average amount of the issue between 1893 and 1898, it is not difficult to see how great the effect must have been. Before closing this section we would call attention to Table V at the end of this chapter, which shows the amount of the issue at the end of each year since 1899. effects on the money market i j 5 Increase of Monetary Facilities Necessitated by the national development after the Sino- Japanese War, the increase and reform of monetary facilities were planned by the government. In the first place the business of the Bank of Japan and of the Yokohama Specie Bank was enlarged, the Hypothec Bank and the Bank of Agriculture and Commerce were established, and in addition industrial banks and the Bank of Formosa were newly es- tablished, in order to meet the needs of the time; and, secondly, a wise disposition of the national banks was made and the causes of economic troubles were removed. The ordinary monetary institutions of Japan had been largely reorganized before the Sino-Japanese War; i.e., on July I, 1893, a com- mercial statute was put into force followed by banking regulations 1 and savings bank regulations, 2 and thus the bank- ing business, which had been under imperfect control be- fore, now entered upon a new era of development. Numer- ous banks were established at this time. But the Bank of Japan and the Yokohama Specie Bank, national banks authorized with the power to issue notes and a few private banks and savings banks may be especially mentioned. Consequently, facilities for supplying capital for commercial purposes seem to have been rather general throughout the country. But the banks for realties and securities had not yet been established. As for facilities for agriculture and in- dustry, there was also a gnat lack here. Consequently the government made endeavors t<> impr monetary facilities, and thus meet the metis of the time. For example, the Hypothec Bank of Japan, the Bank of Agri- culture and Industry, and the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido were established for real property, the Industrial Bank of Japan for securities and the Bank of Formosa to meet the needs in the newly acquired territory of Formosa. As to the Bank of Japan and the Yokohama Specie Bank, the govern- ment, in order to increase their usefulness after the war, 1 Law No. 72, August, 1890. » Law No. 33, August, 1890. \-J() ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR allowed them either to increase their capital or to increase the amount of the securities reserve issue, 1 thereby increasing the loaning power of the banks so that they might contribute toward the betterment of finances after the war. The following record will enumerate the various advance steps made at this time: (i) The Bank of Japan increased her capital by 10 million yen in August, 1895, thus raising her authorized capital from 20 million yen to 30 million yen. (2) The Yokohama Specie Bank increased her capital by 6 million yen in March, 1896, thus raising her authorized capital from 6 million yen to 12 million yen. (3) The Hypothec Bank of Japan (the bank dealing with real property) opened her doors in August, 1897. (4) In each prefecture a bank of agriculture and industry was established between February, 1898, and August, 1900, — forty-six banks in all. (5) The national banks (153 in number) became private banks in February, 1899, and the circulation of national bank notes was prohibited from December 9 of the same year. (6) The Bank of Japan was permitted to increase the amount of her securities reserve issue in March, 1899, by 35 million yen, making the total 120 million yen. 2 (7) The Yokohama Specie Bank increased her capital in September, 1899, by 120 million yen, making her authorized capital 24 million yen. (8) The Bank of Formosa was opened September, 1903. (9) The Colonial Bank of Hokkaido was opened April, 1900. (10) The Industrial Bank of Japan was opened April, 1902. For several years after the war, a period of reform ensued as regarded monetary institutions. The money market, which had already been adjusted to conditions before the war, had now to be steadied by the aid of special banks operated in all directions, so that no more complaints might be raised about the lack of financial facilities. In short, the ten years 1 By Law No. 55, March 9, 1899, the amount was increased from 85 million yen to 120 million yen as before described. 2 Cf. section on expansion of issue capacity of convertible notes, p. 166. EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET / / after the Sino-Japanese War might be designated as the period for perfecting financial facilities. The steady na- tional development after the war and the solid as well as remarkable achievements of national finance may be said to have been due largely to the financial policy of the govern- ment. Of the financial policies mentioned above, we have already dealt with one in detail, viz., the extension of the securities reserve issue (in the section on expansion of issue capacity of convertible notes). We shall now take up the remaining subjects. The Yokohama Specie Bank The Yokohama Specie Bank, at the end of 1893, that is, the year previous to the Sino-Japanese War, had an authorized capital amounting to 6 million yen (with a paid-up capital of 4,500,000 yen). But after the war her business gradually increased. Since February, 1896, the London branch of the bank acted as agent for the Bank of Japan, by taking charge of the indemnity received from China and disposing of it. On July 1, 1895, the Shanghai agency of the bank, which had been closed owing to the Sino-Japanese War, was reopened. On September 15, 1896, an agency was opened at British Hongkong. Furthermore, in July, 1894, increased capital was required by the bank with a view to opening an agency at Bombay, India. So, on March 25, 1896, the authorized capital was increased to 12 million yen. In September, 1899, this amount was doubled, thus becoming 24 million yen. A branch was established at Tientsin (August, 1899), at .Wu- chang (August, 1900), and at Peking (January, 1902), thus extending the sphere of activity in China. A further advance was made in September, 1901, when the by-laws of the bank were revised so that, in ease business transactions abroad required it, the various branches and agents would have power to issue notes payable on sight. In November, 1902, for the first time, such drafts were issued by the Tientsin branch of the bank; in December, by the Shanghai branch; in January, 1903, by the Neuchang branch; and in March by the I78 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR Peking branch. The conditions of loans from 1893 showed a sudden development about 1899, as will be seen from Table VI at the end of this chapter. Realty banks Three kinds of banks were established to deal in real prop- erty, as given below: Name Law governing No. Authorized capital Paid-up capital at time of es- tablishment Opening Hypothec Bank of Japan .... Hank of Agri- culture and Industry . . . Colonial Bank of Hokkaido. No. 82, April 20, 1896. . . Nos. 83 and 84, April 20, 1896 No. 76, March, 1899 1 46 1 Yen 10,000,000 28,370,000 s 3,000,000 Yen 2,500,000 22,923,485 b 1,050,000 Aug. 2, 1897 First on Feb. I, 1898, and last on Aug. 17, 1900 April 1, 1900 Average per bank, 616,739 yen. b Average per bank 498,337 yen. The province of these three kinds of banks was lending money for long terms on real property and at a low rate of interest (in case of the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido, agricul- tural products or shares or bonds might be used as security in place of real property). The object was to improve and develop agriculture and industry. The Hypothec Bank of Japan was established in Tokyo as the central bank for real property, and also one in each of the several prefectures. 1 These banks were to cooperate with the Hypothec Bank in order to supply capital for agriculture and industry. As to the province of the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido, it was not fundamentally different from that of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry, but whereas (i) the shareholders of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry were confined to those who had their residence registered and were actually residing in the prefectures in which the banks were situated, and (2) the amount of subsidy from the government was limited to 5 per cent of the paid-up capital per annum, in the Hokkaido Bank 1 Fu and ken "prefectures" are terms designating administrative districts and first-class local organizations, and their number is 46, that is, 3 fu and 43 ken. The differences between fu and ken are historical rather than substantial. EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 179 these regulations were not and could not be enforced. So, in order to permit special regulations for this bank a separate law was enacted. The amounts expended by the govern- ment as subsidies in the establishment of the banks for real property, as mentioned above, are as follows: Government Subsidies to Hanks Subsidy to Subsidy to Banks Subsidy to War Hypothec Bank of Agriculture and Colonial Bank Total of Japan Industry' of 1 lokkaido Yen Yen Yen Yen 1897 55.052 I,i38,320 a 1. 193.372 1898 30,010 6,2i6,68o a 6,246,690 1899 30,873 688,620 s 250,000 969.493 1900 1 55,000* 250,000 405,000 1901 5,000 200,000 205,000 1902 5,000 200,000 205,000 1903 5,000 5.000 Total U5-935 8,213,620 900,000 9.229,555 » 5,000 yen each year (total 20,000 yen) were subsidies to the Bank of Agriculture and Industry in Okinawa Prefecture (Loochoo). Not only were the foregoing amounts actually expended as subsidies, but in the case of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry and the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido, immunity was given from paying dividends to the government for the shares in its possession for a certain number of years. These arrange- ments helped greatly to realize the object of the subsidii The establishment of bank-- dealing with real property has been advocated from about 1882. But in order to perfect this plan capital for long terms and at low rates of interest was needed. At that time, however, the general interest rate was very high. Some of the national bonds bore more than 7 per cent interest, so that it was not possible to secure low-priced capital. Consequently, it was a matter of the utmost difficulty to secure by mean-- of bond issues amounts several times larger than the capital of the 1 Links. Moreover, the value of land as security was very low, and the circulation of money was not yet free; further, in order to realize profits from agriculture, a longer term is needed for l80 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR loans than is usually allowed by commercial banks. This was the reason why, although financial institutions for facil- itating commercial transactions had been developed, banks for real property had not yet been established; thus the capital needed for agriculture and industry was lacking, and conse- quently their full development could not readily be effected. But the tendency in the money market was toward a gradual fall in the interest rate. In addition, the price of bonds rose. With the promulgation of the law concerning consolidated bonds in 1886, bonds bearing high interest disappeared and the price of bonds showed signs of a steady rise. Thus a favorable opportunity for establishing banks for real property had come. When the Bank of Japan lowered the rate of interest after the Sino-Japanese War, the prices of securities rose. On account of anxiety as to the inflow of the indemnity the interest rate was lowered, bonds and shares rose in price, and the proposal to issue bonds to secure capital to be loaned by the banks for real property was received with great favor. At last the laws governing the Hypothec Bank of Japan and the Banks of Agriculture and Industry were promulgated. We shall now briefly explain the method of organization. (A) The Hypothec Bank of Japan and the Banks of Agri- culture and Industry were closely related to each other. Both aimed at loaning capital for the improvement and develop- ment of agriculture and industry, with real property as security. The difference between the two was only that of size and position; that is, the Hypothec Bank was the central bank, while local Banks of Agriculture and Industry were established in the different prefectures. The Hypothec Bank lent capital to the Banks of Agriculture and Industry by taking the bonds issued by the latter banks. The Banks of Agriculture and Industry acted as agents for the Hypothec Bank. The two helped each other in supplying capital to agriculture and industry. (B) The capital of the Hypothec Bank was 10,000,000 yen and its shares were valued at 200 yen each, whereas the EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 181 capital of the various Banks of Agriculture and Industry was not more than 200,000 yen each, and their shares were valued at 20 yen each. There was only one Hypothec Bank established in Japan, whereas the other banks were numerous — one in each prefecture— and their shareholders were re- quired to have their residences registered, and actually to live in said prefecture. 1 In accordance with the purpose for which they were es- tablished, the loans were made with real property as security, 2 and on the annual instalment system. In the case of the Hypothec Bank these were fifty-year, and in the case of other banks, thirty-year instalments. In addition, loans might be made on a system of regular instalments for five years, the limit being one-tenth of the amount mentioned above (Hy- pothec Bank) or one-fifth (Banks of Agriculture and Industry). (C) The capital was represented principally by the capital of each bank, but the most important matter to be considered was the issue of bonds. When one-fourth or more of the capital was paid up, the Hypothec Bank might issue bonds to within ten times the paid-up capital and not exceeding the amount of the loans payable by annual instalments and the amount of the accepted bonds of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry, while the Banks of Agriculture and Industry might issue bonds to within five times the paid-up capital and not exceeding the loans by annual instalments minus the amount borrowed from the Hypothec Bank. The bonds were valued at 10 yen and up- ward with premium in the case of the Hypothec Bank, and at 5 yen and upward in the ease of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. The reason why the value- were fixed so low was because thus the banks might be able to gather in -mall amounts as capital. (D) These two kinds of banks were under the control of the Minister of Finance. In case the dividends of the Hy- 1 The registry ..i" residence means registry in the locality where is kept the book ristry hi' the family <>i" which one is a member. 1 Public corporations were exempted from furnishing this security. [82 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR pothec Bank should fall below 5 per cent, the Bank was to receive a subsidy for ten years from the time of its establish- ment. In the case of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry the various prefectures, in accordance with the law of subsidy to the Banks of Agriculture and Industry 1 were to be allowed to have capital to invest in the shares of the Banks to the limit of 70 yen per hundred cho of taxable land, not in- cluding house lots, mineral-water sites, or swamp grounds of the various prefectures; also to the limit of a total of 300,000 yen per prefecture and not exceeding one-third of the paid-up capital. Further, from the time of the establishment of the banks it was arranged that no dividends should be required for ten years for the shares subscribed by the prefectural gov- ernments, and for 5 years more the dividends should be in- cluded in the reserve fund. We shall explain later about the amount supplied. In this way, middle-class farmers and industrialists who had been inconvenienced by the high rates of interest uni- versally prevalent gained relief. In accordance with the foregoing system, the Hypothec Bank was established in June, 1897, with a capital of 10 million yen and a paid-up capital of 2\ million yen. The doors of the Hypothec Bank were opened August 2, 1897. A Bank of Agriculture and Industry was established in each prefecture, the first being the one in Tokyo prefecture established on December 28, 1897, and the last being the one established in Tokushima prefecture on August 9, 1900 — forty-six in all. At the end of December, 1900, the year in which the establishment of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry was completed, the total amount of authorized capital was 28,370,000 yen, and the total paid-up capital 22,- 923,485 yen, of which 8,178,620 yen was the amount of the government subsidy, in accordance with the law of subsidy, to the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. At the time of their establishment, it happened that the money market was tight and there was a great demand for capital. So loans 1 Law No. 84, April 20, 1896. EFFECTS OX Till- MONEY MARKET 183 were steadily made and a great service was thn^ rendered agriculture and industry by these banks. In the case of the Hypothec Bank, between 1898 and 1903 the total amount of bonds issued was 72,557,820 yen. At the end of each year the amounts loaned dwindled, according to the nature of the loan, some being repaid in annual instalments, some at regular periods. The figures are as follows: Outstanding Loans for Various Purposes at End of Each Year, 1897-1903 Year Agriculture Industry Public corporations" Public associations 1 " Total Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen 1897 342,709 816,600 10,000 206,703 I,376,oi2 1898 1,426,257 4.477.939 313.593 488,945 6,706,734 1899 2,328,762 4,886,682 539.425 i,oi9,973 8,774.842 1 900 3.477.737 5.873.213 1,075.883 1,223,798 11,650,631 1901 4,565,202 6,451.573 1,601,883 1,429,920 14,048,578 1 902 6,348,882 7.559.603 1,780,858 1,609,659 17,320,102° 1903 8,544,907 7,982,041 3,044,512 1,940,674 2i,795,394 d » Includes loans to prefectures, counties, cities, towns and villages. 1 Includes loans to water improvement guilds, earth-work guilds and arable land adjustment guilds. • Includes 21,100 yen, loans of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. d Includes 283,260 yen, loans of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. The amounts of the bonds of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry taken over were not included in the foregoing tabic They were as follows: Year 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Face value Yen 142,280 1 75,580 239.390 442,610 Price Yen 137.344 170,644 234.454 KJ7.799 565,401 Now, by examining the Banks of Agriculture and Industry, we find the amounts of the bonds of those banks reached 7,033,430 yen between 1899 and 1903, and the amounts of the loans, those redeemable by annual instalments and those redeemable at regular periods, are shown in Table VII at the end of this chapter. 1 1 Post, p. 202. [84 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Again, in order to show the power of the banks to do busi- ness in spite of the figures, two additional tables VIII and IX have been inserted at the end of this chapter. 1 Let us consider next the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido. Its purpose was the same as that of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry of the various prefectures, but Hokkaido was dif- ferent from other parts of the country in that the circulation of money was not yet sufficient, and in consequence the interest rate was very high. It was not easy, therefore, to establish a bank with qualifications as to shareholders, profits and subsidy the same as for the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. So the sphere of activity of this bank was made a little broader, and as we have briefly explained before, a special law was framed to permit a special kind of subsidy for it. The authorized capital was 3 million, yen of which 1 million yen was furnished by the government, and on the government shares no dividends were required for ten years after the last day of the first period of the establishment. The business of the bank was begun on April 1, 1900, with a paid-up capital of 750,000 yen. Although the sphere of activity of this bank was in the main the same as that of the other Banks of Agriculture and Industry, yet there were some differences. For example, as this bank was not only to loan money on the security of real property, but also to furnish capital for the development of the land of Hokkaido, loans were made with agricultural products, shares and bonds as security, bonds were subsidized, and the business of handling deposits and drafts was under- taken; in short the sphere of activity was somewhat broader than that of the Banks of Agriculture and Industry. Funds for the business were obtained, in addition to the bank's capital, by issuing bonds (colonial bank bonds) to the limit of five times the paid-up capital. The actual business condition of the bank is shown by the following table of loans made: 1 Post, pp. 203-205. EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET Loans of Colonial Bank of Hokkaido Year To Agriculture and industry To Industry To Com- merce To public institutions Total 1900 Instalment Regular period Total Yen 492,786 36,840 Yen 82,821 Yen 30,000 Yen 12,620 3-500 Yen 618,227 40,340 529,626 82,821 30,000 16,120 658,567 1901 Instalment Regular period Total Yen 913.540 221,200 Yen 126,921 103,400 Yen 25,183 5.000 Yen 12,353 Yen 1,077.997 329,600 M34.740 230,321 30,183 12,353 1,407.597 1902 Instalment Regular period Total Yen 1,031,781 247,460 Yen 152,014 128,000 Yen 166,728 Yen 51,864 40,000 Yen 1,402,387 415,460 1,279,241 280,014 166,728 91,864 1,817,847 1903 Instalment Regular period Total Yen 1,183,176 427,741 Yen 109,706 113,600 Yen 242,858 80,700 Yen 40,223 40,000 Yen 1,575.963 662,041 1,610,917 224,306 323.558 80,223 2,238,004 As for the capital used in the business of the bank, the colonial bank bonds were issued until 1904. The rest was as follows : Paid-up capital Reserve Percentage of dividends Loans Year Total in year Balam end of year 1900 1901 1902 1903 }'( n 1 ,(.50,00(1 2,098,406 2,100,000 2, 700,000 Yen 2,343 15.248 76,400 106,600 7.0 : s ,, 8.0 Yen 723.435 1,911,118 3.532, 080 5.287,744 Yen 703.544 1 .501 2,102,857 2,646,278 Total . . . 7,0 p, |oo 200,, SO I ii.454.377 6,954 Bank oj Formosa The Bank of Formosa was established in accordance with Law No. 38 of March, 1897,' as the central financial institu- 1 Concerning the Bank of Formosa. [86 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR tion of Formosa, with the object of furnishing capital for commerce, industry and public works, of developing the economic resources of Formosa, and of extending the scope of business of the Bank to South China and the South Sea Islands by providing a financial organ for the commerce of these countries; the Bank was also intended to secure the economic independence of Formosa and reform the monetary system. The government believed that the sound develop- ment of Formosa could not be hoped for unless protection was given to the Bank, in view of the conditions prevailing in the island, where everything was still undeveloped, peace and order were not yet secured, and the credit system was not yet established. So, by Law No. 35 of March 1, 1899, 1 (1) 2 million yen of silver were lent to the Bank without interest, to be used exclusively as a reserve fund for the conversion of notes, (2) 1 million yen of the 5 million yen capital of the Bank were subscribed by the government. In addition, it was arranged that the dividends on shares payable to the government should be transferred for five years to the reserve fund for meeting the losses of the Bank, thereby making the establishment of the Bank easier, and then on July 27 of the same year, the silver 2 million yen were exchanged for 2,127,- 659 pieces of silver yen in coins (94 sen per 1 piece) and these were paid to the Bank together with 54 sen of auxiliary silver coins, thereby fulfilling the duty of subsidizing the Bank. The Bank on July 22, 1899, secured 1,250,000 yen or one- fourth of the authorized capital of 5 million yen, and the doors were opened on September 26. This Bank, as the central bank, has the power to issue notes. At first by Article VIII of the law concerning the Bank of Formosa, this Bank was authorized to issue notes valued at 5 yen and upward redeemable in gold. But the conditions in the island were not yet such as to need this conversion into gold. So by Law No. 34 of March, 1899, this regulation was changed and the Bank was empowered to issue notes redeem- able in silver coin valued at 1 yen and upward. As to regula- 1 Concerning a subsidy to the Bank of Formosa. EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET I8 7 tions for the reserve, to guarantee the issue of silver certificates, specie (gold or silver) to the amount of one-half and upward of the issue was to be kept as a reserve. For the rest, up to the limit of 5 million yen, government notes, convertible bank notes and other reliable certificates or commercial checks could be made a guarantee. Again, in case of need of a further issue of notes, the same amount of guarantee reserve was to be kept in readiness and the tax on the issue at the rate of 5 per cent per annum or upward was to be paid. Bank notes were issued for the first time on September 29 to the amount of 490,000 yen. The following table will show the actual condition of the business from September, 1899, to December, 1903. 1 Specie Resen, e Date Guarantee Total reserve Gold Silver Total Yen Yen Yt>i Yen Yen Sept., 1899 449,098 449,098 449,098 Oct., 1899 1 ,050,000 1,050,000 1,050,000 Nov., 1899 1,523.337 1.523.337 1.523.337 Dec, 1899 1,834.917 1. 834.91 7 1,834.917 Dec., 1900 494.276 1.577.5*5 2,071,861 1 511.529 1.390 Dec, 1901 [,829,358 1.829,358 1.370,371 3.199.729 Dec, 1902 3,35^.7"' 3.352,719 1,74(1,447 5,099,166 Dec, 1903 222,222 2,219,303 2,441.525 2,181,989 4.623,514 Total 716,498 13.836,317 14,552,81s 6,810,336 21,363,151 Again, the average annual amounts of issue at the month's end were as follows: Yi .ir Spo ie reserve Guarantee < rve Total Gold Silver Total 1 899 Yen 352,134 -".548 614.368 Yen 1,2] . 2,017 [,92« 2.799.*N> 2,027,593 Yen 1,214,338 2,369,702 1,976,232 2.799.**<> 2,64I,96l Yen -.707 [,486,970 1 ,650,9 \o 2,222,150 Yen 1,21 3.837409 3,463,202 4,450,820 4,864,1 1 1 1900 1901 1902 1903 Total 1 .1117,050 9,985,063 I I,0O2,] 13 7,767 17.^29,880 1 88 FXONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINOJAPANESE WAR As shown in the foregoing table, the Bank of Formosa gradually extended the scope of its business. It established branches on the mainland of Japan, and branches and agencies in Amoy, Hongkong and other places ; thereby more and more perfectly rendering the service for which it was established. Table X at the end of this chapter 1 sets forth the principal facts as to the Bank's activities in recent years. Industrial Bank of Japan The Industrial Bank of Japan was established as a realty bank. It was based upon Law No. 70 of March, 1900. About 1890 our national finance was freed from the evils of incon- vertible notes. When certain new enterprises were under- taken and the money circulation became tight, the government ordered the Bank of Japan to initiate the so-called security system, that is, to give discount or allow an overdraft for a certain amount of shares as guarantee in order to relieve the urgent needs of the industrial world, and at the same time to take over the loans made in accordance with the security system mentioned above, by establishing a bank for personal- ties. That was how the Industrial Bank of Japan came to be established. About ten years later, when at the close of the Sino- Japanese War new enterprises were projected, and as capital was insufficient it became necessary to plan the importation of foreign capital, this Bank was established to meet the need. The Bank's authorized capital amounted to 10 million yen, and with the passage of the industrial bank law its establish- ment was planned. But at that time the money circulation was tight and did not permit the opening of the Bank. So the issue of shares was postponed for a time. The restoration of a favorable money market was awaited. At last, in March, 1902, 2,500,000 yen were paid in, as the first instalment on the shares of the Bank, and the doors were opened on April 10 of the same year. The Bank was to make loans on the security of national bonds, bonds of local governments and 1 Post p. 20 5. EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET 1 89 the bonds and shares of various companies, and to underwrite these. It was empowered to secure a part of the capital for its business by issuing industrial bank bonds. The limit of the bond issue was fixed at five times the paid-up capital or not to exceed the actual amount of the loans or the local government bonds or company bonds then in t lie hands of the Bank. Table XI at the end of this chapter 1 shows the actual re- sults of the business of this Bank. Conditions in the Banking Industry In the foregoing section we have explained in detail how the government, to encourage the national development after the Sino-Japanese War, helped to establish various special banks, and, by enlarging the spheres of the ordinary banks which had been established before the war, planned to reform the monetary system. With the change in economic conditions after the war, the government was able to solve the problem of what disposition to make of the national banks, which had been pending since before the war, and thereby added to the stability of the monetary system. This should be especially noted as a result brought about by the war. The system of national banks was established in accordance with Law No. 349, with the object of redeeming the govern- ment notes which had been recklessly issued since the begin- ning of the Meiji Era (1868) and of facilitating the circulation of commercial capital. We shall here briefly explain the method of issue of these bank notes. The national banks offered the government notes in exchange for public loan bonds — redeemable in gold certificates, and then by offering the latter received bank notes. The national bank notes were convertible in specie. Bui at that time our country exported gold and silver, especially gold, to an enormous amount. The price of gold coin rose, so thai there came to be a difference between gold certificates and gold coin, 2 and the national banks 1 Post, p. 206. 2 Between July 1873 and 1876 the highest dilTerence was 4.9 per cent, in March, 1876. I«)0 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR could no longer issue bank notes. Consequently, the manage- ment of these banks became very difficult, and only four or five of them were established. The government in order to encourage the establishment of national banks and enable them to accomplish the original purpose and at the same time to maintain the price of the enormous amount of bonds newly issued at the time the change in the system was made, changed the system of specie conversion into the system of conversion into currency, that is, government notes, by Law No. 1 06 of August, 1876. Thus appeared the incon- vertible bank notes. After this banks were established one after another, 153 banks being established from September, 1876, to November, 1879, with a paid-up capital amounting in all to 40,616,063 yen, while the notes issued amounted to 34,046,014 yen. But, later, the government notes were not redeemed at all, and at the end of January, 1878, the highest point was reached, the notes issued amounting to 139,301,593 yen. Moreover, the inconvertible bank notes increased gradually and the price of notes decreased until, in 1881, the lowest point was touched when the difference between notes and specie reached 93 per cent against gold and 79.5 per cent against Mexican silver. Thereupon the government decided to redeem the various notes and at the same time to change the system. Separate banks were replaced by one central bank and in 1882 the Bank of Japan was established; 1 from 1884 convertible bank notes were issued. 2 Again the government, by Law No. 14, of June, 1885, decided to begin the conversion of government notes into silver coins in January, 1886. 3 In regard to these banks, it must be added that the government revised the national-bank regulations on May 5, 1883 4 thereby fixing the period of existence at twenty years in full from the day the permit was issued; the term limit of the banks ex- pired between September, 1886, and December, 1899. Fur- 1 Law No. 32 of 1882. 2 Law No. 18 of May, 1884. 3 At the end of 1885 the government notes amounted to 88,345,096 yen. 4 Law No. 14. EFFECTS OX THE MONEY MARKET I9I thermore, it was decided to redeem the bank notes, amount- ing to 31,812,880 yen, which existed at the time by the following method. This was called the united method of re- demption of national bank notes. As for a while it caused a great sensation in political circles after the Sino-Japanese War, we shall briefly explain below this method of redemption. (1) The national banks shall deposit with the Bank of Japan, for conversion of the notes a reserve (currency) amounting to one-fourth of the notes allowed them, which reserve shall be kept as a time deposit during the years in which the banks are operated, to be applied to the redemption of the notes (first class redemption fund). (2) The national banks shall set aside out of their profits at the end of each half year an amount equal to 2.5 per cent per annum of the amount of the notes allowed them and shall deposit this with the Bank of Japan as a fund for the redemp- tion of the notes (second class redemption fund). (3) The Bank of Japan shall purchase interest-bearing bonds with the foregoing sums and shall redeem notes with the interest and transfer the notes to the Department of Finance. The Department of Finance shall then hand over public loan bonds to said bank equal in amount to those redeemed. According to the estimate at the time, the market price of the public loan bonds bearing 7 per cent interest was expected to be as mentioned below, as the result of which transaction the amount of interest on bonds purchased up to 1897 with the first-class redemption fund would amount to [0,738,982 yen, and the amount of the face value of the bonds purchased with the second-class redemption fund to 13. 791, 515 yen and the interest to 7,992,224 yen, totaling 32,522,721 yen. This plan was to leave a certain amount of surplus compared with the existing amount of the notes, the banks being able to redeem a greater part of the notes with a portion of the in- terest of the reserve fund and the profits at the time of the expiration of the business term. Moreover, it was expected that the public loan bonds and the reserve fund would remain in the possession of the bank, and that the notes issued would 192 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR return to the bank indirectly in the form of currency, so that the problem would be satisfactorily solved. But this plan was impracticable for two reasons. One was that the price of bonds rose, and the other that the bonds bearing 7 per cent interest disappeared. For the former reason the amount needed to purchase the bonds was reduced. For the latter the amount of interest was reduced. The following table will show a comparison between the price of bonds as estimated at the time of the initiation of the united plan of redemption and that actually received : Comparison of Estimated and Actual Price of Bonds, 1 883-1 895 Year Estimated price of bonds Rate of interest Actual price of bonds Rate of interest 188"? Yen 80,000 80,000 80,000 85,000 85,000 85,000 85,000 90,000 90,000 90,000 90,000 95,000 90,000 Per cent 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 Yen 83,947 93,393 96,331 107,309 101,578 101,445 101,015 99,866 100,451 101,726 106,962 105,270 99,703 Per cent 7 1884 7 188s 7 1886 7 1887 5 1888 5 1889 5 1 890 5 1891 5 5 180-1 5 1 8qa 5 t8q<; 5 The difference between the estimated price and the actual market price was as just stated. Moreover, in 1886, the law of consolidated bonds was established, and from March, 1887, the bonds of 5 per cent or above were redeemed so that it became impossible to purchase 7 per cent bonds. These facts produced a great miscalculation in the estimate of the redemption fund. Thereupon, the national banks asked for a postponement of the right to issue notes, in order to make up for the losses arising from the miscalculation mentioned above. The gov- ernment on the other hand tried to deprive them of their special privilege upon the expiration of the business term and EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET I 93 to change them into private banks, only thus allowing them to continue their business (advocacy for continuation). Thus the two diverse opinions, as to extension or continuation, constituted a great problem for the nation, especially for the Diet, from ante-war times. But after the war, the confusion in the money market increased, so that the advocates of extension gained the upper hand, enthusiastically upholding this doctrine on the ground that the future money market would become tighter and the price of bonds would fall, and that the reason why the price of bonds, which had risen ordinarily at the time of the Sino-Japanese War, was main- tained, lay in the fact that the national banks needed them. For a while many people considered this view as being a reasonable one. So the government by law ordered the Bank of Japan to lend capital for the redemption of notes amounting to 22 million yen, without interest, in order to relieve the national banks from the difficulties which had arisen from the aforementioned miscalculation. But, fortunately, from the latter half of 1895 the market value of securities generally rose and with renewed activity in industrial and commercial circles the banking business became most profitable. So the once powerful advocates of the doctrine of extension lost their influence, and a bill embodying the first principle, that of continuation, was passed by the Imperial Diet, and at last the 153 national banks disappeared altogether from the eco- nomic world in February, 1899. Of these 153 banks, 8 dissolved of themselves on the expiration of their terms, 16 amalgamated and 7 closed their doors. Only 122 continued as private institutions. Of these, 30 were changed after, and 92 before, the expiration of their term. We have so far explained the problem of adjustment connected with the national banks. We shall now glance at the banking business in general. In the first place, as a re- sult of this reconstruction of the national banks, a number of specially privileged banks, including the Bank of Japan, the Yokohama Specie Bank, the National Bank, the Hypothec Bank of Japan, the Banks of Agrirulture and Industry, the 14 194 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Colonial Bank of Hokkaido, the Industrial Bank of Japan, the Bank of Formosa, and a number of ordinary banks, were considerably changed, as shown below: Increase IN Number of Banks, 1 893-1903 Main Banks Total Branch Banks Year Special banks Ordinary banks Savings banks Special banks Ordinary S, banks t ivings >anks Total 1893..- 135 545 23 i a 703 162 165 12 339 1894.. . 135 700 30 i a 865 188 196 30 414 1895-- • 135 792 ' 86 6 a 1,013 193 277 107 577 1896.. . 123 1,005 149 , 44 a 1,277 180 428 224 832 1897.- • 61 1,223 221 , 91* 1,505 83 651 270 1,004 1898.. . 48 1,444 260 ,i58 a i,752 18 912 453 1,383 1899.. . 49 1,561 333 l 198* i,943 30 1,069 631 1,730 1900. . . 51 1,802 419 262* 2,272 32 1,374 814 2,220 1901.. . 51 1,867 441 ,273 s 2,359 33 i,457 ^542 >337 a 2,032 1902.. . 52 1,841 431 270* 2,324 34 1,470 536 ,33i a 2,040 1903- • • 52 1,754 469 L 2I9 a 2,275 35 1,441 58b 291" 2,062 •Ordinary banks conducting savings business so their number waa not included in the total figures. Table XII at the end of this chapter 1 will show the amount of capital, deposits, net profits, and dividends of these banks. The following table will show the amounts of deposits and loans for the various banks : 2 l Post, p. 207. 2 The special banks include the Bank of Japan, the National Banks (up to the end of 1898), the Yokohama Specie Bank, the Hypothec Bank of Japan (after 1897), the Banks of Agriculture and Industry (after 1898), the Bank of Formosa (after 1899), the Colonial Bank of Hokkaido (after 1900), and the Industrial Bank of Japan (after 1902). EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET Bank Deposits and Loans 195 Deposits Loans Year Amount Percentage (1893=100) Amount Percentage (1893=100) 1893 Yen 115. 139.920 138,452,655 190,840,473 430,234,984 383,910,820 400,892,757 606,053,315 610,010,408 604,618,138 712,677,790 778,514,683 100. 120.2 165-7 373-7 333-4 438.2 526.4 529 -8 525-1 619.0 676.1 Yen 195.017,509 227,909,656 322,645,257 543,823,073 500,821,394 648,390,268 882,574,248 992,247,666 921,074,784 991,138,278 1,046,774,556 100. 1894 116. 9 165.2 278.9 256.8 332.5 452.6 508.8 472.3 508.2 536.8 1895 1 896 1897 1898 1 899 1900 1901 1902 1903 4.971.345.943 7,272,416,689 The foregoing figures show the conditions of the banks in Japan after the Sino-Japanese War. In point of capital, deposits and loans, all made rapid progress. Especially in 1899 was their development very remarkable, after the period of adjustment of the national banks. All this followed as a result of the activity of economic circles after the war, but the reconstruction of the national banks had a great deal to do with producing this prosperous condition. Therefore, we can not but recognize the fact that the war after all had no small effect upon the banking industry. I96 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR 3 U 01 bO in a o> •4-> O CO^O fOt^t^O ~oo 8 a N CI CO CO CO "*■ M M M It M M c 01 Cu J jO c c VO IO T}- t^ tJ- t^ On CN • — CO lOOO CO O O CS 10 o> *^j NO tJ- w vO rf « r^vo rt 3 8 m <*• r-» on cn •*■ .• cO. CS vO ^3 !2 « w Ov"t tJ-00 >-" 10 r^ is c3 >,0>m N OON ON ON ,° a 00 no t>. r^ 10 co^ Hh IO T? no" IO rf i-T rC cT rj-^w _, h m •N CO ON lO^O O 00 1-1 ■0 -o — 1 10 no 00 nom no cs "c3 N» WiO "» ^ s: iotsM osvo "i. °°. ^ °- w . °- CO 00 H O0_ (N|_ 00" 0" r^ o" »o of no"-* !-• CO fOfO^-' "tj Q, 5 Oih O !ON N 00 11 cd Oh S" N M O M cOnO " OnnO O CO On N t<-3- c CONO »O00 lO t^vO M NO CO >* 00 t^OO t^NO n CO c ,_ M _, HI 1-1 M ^ On On CM ON cONO co r^ t^- "+ ^ O too ON CO c 8 »OnO_ (H_ t); N O; 10 CO "o U ,« INN m'miO C> 00 t^ J^, 0> ,WQ^ »< QU Q Q EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 197 Percentage compared with issue t^. o^o o> O O « « >t POOO m mOMO O*. C*- POOO* c> 0" «f pj rO »*o 00 00 O <-o N pO 00* pO °- PO .§ O -7 3 m 00 NOMO ■ iAh • \o "2» 8 ! r". PO ! P* vO >-" ^ . OOO . •- ~ °0 2 * J 00 m^o 00 « W O •*■ m t^oq_oo_ o_ cr> o_ Jl, O_00 rttON «1C 00* c". O* 00" 0' ^ 0" -+• -1-00 0>N OMO — - >-• >- (N M N 00 pO "2 00" PO 10 w Month-end guarantee reserve issue P< O^OO •*■ ID P» •-• m O - OOOiO N \0 - >o O00 tJ- NOO" ^lONNO 00 ON 10 Month-end specie reserve issue -• 0>U>O^N POO 8 30 00* O* O* m O* p" ,*» (N 11 r-» rovo r^ if Hi O t^. rO r^ P< 10 .-> «"> M O* P* 00* O. O* 00 00O to Onoo >-• p* p>- 00* vO rt 9 g pO -t- uovO r^oo Q\ Qs o^ O^ O* s O^ 00 00 00 00 00 00 00 c h 198 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR 4J bCTJ 4> rt no on 0) Q."* h (H 'tO* t: b-5 (U . r Oh u :S s £ On rf O>00 NO 00 N co 3 • 00 (Ort")H 10 00 01 in 8 • vo_ q_ m q_ o_ "} 10 wc- 1 ' Tf 0" M in »o to NO S*a 1000 00 toio« 10 4) 3 00 On *nO t^NO^ 10 > C & tooo" cf 0" **■ cS < i-i CO >0 "0*0 CO 4-1 OOO f^ On IO 00 tj- rj- mo ro IO 3- 03 '-T 3 8 ! t-^ CO ! fN vO ~> t-; 2 . -h n to ►* o_ to o_ r^ to rf in t^. •* 0" lO **" CS CM m n> CM "* vO 3 00 5 (S NO 00 8 on • • o_ • • • w • ; 00" ; ; ; On On Res stren IS! £ N . . O* . . . M IO r^ «" to Tj" •O - o> t^- 0* NO GJ (/) JL w 8 ' O tO O ««nO 00 NO •fl'-* . 10 t^ iOnO fO On t~» 4-1 §5 £ mio vo_ in t-;.oo_ NO m i-T cf t-^00" w O" £2 co •* r^ ■* CO end tee ssue t^vO N fO O O 1^ on O o^t^mm r~» t>~ ■* O On 0_ N m •5 § se 8 . 0" m d\ rT 10 >o >* 1 . NO CO ^ CO OOO in s St: . fO W 00_ CM C_vO * O 3 4) • 10 t-icx in in tC CO IT3 vO * t^ CM 4J "T3 > iO OnnO t^ CO CO to cm »-« t^ 10 cs m lO • cs t~;Nq_ 0^ r-~\o On onth-( cie res issue 8 ! 0~ *i «-<" ti ►-" to t~^ >> ►h «o to Tj- M lO >H ' "2oo_ > "ed "c3 a CO "*• »o\o 1^00 Ov E On On On On On On On 00 00 00 00 00 00 00 — — — — — — — EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 199 M 3 a o Q 01 ~ £ o J3 C, N«- C O 00 t N A M . ^ t *t ^ .. ■<"■ -OO" -f l^. -f -f K ,> O "-• rO 0_ ►* CO N "i ■*". °. "i , 00 n vo 10 . *3-00 O rO o 3 tJ-CO 1- o rr t-» r» c^ OO* r*5 M SO iTSvO rOOO «N"< m M •- OO ft rf ■->" 00* O^ ^0 10 t^ «» CS O l^fjt^t^^ rO * »C*0 t^OO O ^ ^ O^O^ ^ ^ O^ 00 00 00 OC 00 00 00 20O ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR 4> 3 CO CO 3 C C a o M 03 u U > < 4> O bflO c || dJ 00 s OOO ID COOO ;£ o in^o \0 co ^OOOiO^O ■M c 3 O S < CN 00 CO O CN Cp N *« O *0 CN_ CN vO vO_ 8 (O N O Tj- h*i CO t^>0 >-i 00 -t lO N N h O O 00 00 O m N M M « 0) 3 co CO to CU V» °C 3 o 0> en i. T 3 eg to u.co ICtOlOO CO O OvO °o cr> co in a o ; ^ CN CS CO t-» . " ^ N . ^ ^ • O* M CN cn CN -*CN i_ u % U t^o 0*0 t-» 00 <^ to 1/5 CO 8 & o"oo" iooo~ ^ m « CONIO ""t 1 ^ Q Q O M CN~ CN *n ■*vO rj- CN •-> < •o > O. (n C/) 4) vO tN »^ ►" 00 W M CO00_ M a M~ c£oo~ 00~ «N ^ rt- it- m >-• ^o l*( M COMM O O t^ M O>^o"" « r^O « la CO CU 00000 00 OOOO EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 201 o»o»n a^t^.ior< foift5>^ -i C50O O 1^ P< rO O00 I/O O 00 M 00 t^QO M-'^-'~OrO-t'l-a^C v x« >-i PO ro "3" rO n •»*■ o\ .= ui t^ t^ p< *n 00 O NvO 0>«N O I/O *- n ~ H . . — 00 r>- •<*• O* 2 o .^- 00 t^O O* noO IO ^-i "J 00 . °l "3 c^ 00 - x« Q JiMiO P4 O O 00 i/)0\NN POO « « N PI OOO 0*00 t^tN l/J-tN* ro c ^ °. N . "2 "^ ^ 't t ? a l ia . ^ 3 O 8 8 r-^o" tr> no" ro \r> <-T i/ioo 0" »Jx o\ 1/500 C5«- ON rt u cC *?. "I °. "2 ""t 00 .. "2 ^t T t'^L *1 e» Tcmpor ansasfo exchan s ro cf 10 100* 00" 1/0 n «*5 ci" i> n •*■ r^ O »0O 00 nn a> 1*1 C,x (OxiOO O O^M Nljv 00_ m ~T cT 00" o "~* w •° o ovr^'J-x-i o\fs o>wn 1/1 rs IO 00 xio O N i-^^xao >t 10 4-> o lOO n O 10 .*> >-iO icao r^o xiiocoo 00 i_ — x>i r>.t^— 00 ■* -f -^-O n >o "I V 4> x< tsi x> rs 1*} to t*J «♦> **5 00" 1 c (S O 3 u 0} OS IO00 NNOOlONxN 0000 »no "t-aN n c « idoo 00 « 10 n q> o_ ►» ■* u^ CM o_ C ro ;> •? -f "5 t*^ *f xT pC n O" >OC -iPI N N O^sO O x. js * ■S — > x. c. tU- t t w o m" Q -r in os ri-oo 00 x- xf t^. 10 — n 1^ O 1^00 NO* Tf-sO f^O ■ 1^ q w c -re q c oo_oo_ q_ 00 c B e> ^0" 0" 0" «^. 1 » ifl 1 » O r i* 0" a -i- o k-i 1^00 x. ts| 1- I^oo X/iON O o__ J •*■ m no n stf.c a n « 2 ^i H n -t-i/~.o t^» O^C x- (si t*5 ffi^OM^CT>ff>0<0 O O O 00 00 X 00 00 00 X o^c 202 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR o < 3 O H ON On On CN a r~" co ■ *> 00 to Pn \q m to 00 s ^ ^ ■^ ON CN « cjq ON to r«« NO CN o_ to CN 00 Tt 00 CN CN CN «HN K^ O O « SCO M CO CN "2 00* o_ 10 CN Yen 24,296,668 3,392,100 00 NO ts 00* 00 NO ts CN CO *E "2 IP «*. : to CO m ON CO w CN Tt r^ a cn no ^0*1-* ?H vO >- «o CO ON t^ ts to ■ c # o *4J la a u O o t o 3 PL, 4-> — c cd ts w O CN 00 o oo r^ d m On O ON ID O w O 00 « O M On O O M 00 d NO M <-> rs c e 3 O i < tsOO 00 Tt a "2*1 5 «o>i »o CO 00 no" Tt tO a"°- 5 Tt-ON KL On ■* CN to o_ 00 On O NO a^^ S; cono 1^ O* CO oo. 00 m O NO a *i "t § ONNO Si t>. CN "no CO CO «9 «o 8 CN* 00 00 a «.**: 5 CN lO K-mLO -,nO O tot-; to>-r CO CO CN* r^ o_ 10 >o CN On a "2^ S; no m s; no co q;c» t? « IO to CN* O OO. NO* CN Tt NO ts § cots ^ N O ts iS NO to Tt O CN 6" U 4-» CO 3 "O C 4-» ^^ C to CU 4-> o o a, o i- co CO CN o fO ■^-On « CM lO CN c 3 O E < CM O Tj-O a <*L"2 ►*> Ttto HH ION N "2 ts is °i COON t^ CO a "2 °Z £> toro rH NO lO tN (N m ON o_ to r^ cn ON ON a o.« ^ O CN ?H \0 On o_t^ ON 00 CN. CN* lO 00 O r^ a q.o. ^ 00 n- ?n -* Tt- ON On 00 q. CN* ON °°. IO 00 ON a "^"^ ^ CnT« >< CN Tt « On in CN ts Tt NO O NO* 00 O 00 NO a ° *1 *j> & 0* Tt rs in 001 Tt to 00* in N NO* c .2 a E cu "O 0) Oh CO CO CO CO OB CO 4-» 4-» 4-J 4-» 4)3 4J C C C C C G £ to £ to £ co £ co £ co £ co E"0 Etj E-o E-o Et3 E-o TO •£ CO »r4 TO »^ TO •£ TO • — TO "r* too COO) co cu to cu CO CU 7. CU .E °" — .S °" — . c a — .E °* — .E °* — .E a — ^^UTO _ *-• CCj ]]] u rt 'JZ u ^ ^_ u. rt * ( U TO «i2 o ^J2 o ""3.2 o Hj2 o «iS o cojS o 3 3 £ 3 3 r" 33 {2 33 £ 33 f2 => 3 £ ecu ecu c J* ■* On 00 On On 00 C O ON ON CN O ON to ON 1 1 EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 203 204 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR en 2 Q H •- 1 8 Q ° « 1 g .5 H Cs « si < 8 X -a c • Os i Os iO CN co as 4) ■MNOOO't^ so •4-» U • M 0_ 00_ 1"; "eh 0; ^ .*> CN sO O 00 •- 00 " w - °- °i °- *1 °°- vO rt BlM "2 g eU O rf oT O^ CO lO t-^ n M M N (S CI en d c m O NOvi^aH a\ (0 CO **• "3"sO O "0 sO 3 • iouin •"4-co m VO O „ ,\ON« O00 fO Os j3 a 8 , iOm N 0>0 "5 "* o H »*» co t-;co_ "5 't °1 **■ ci o" iooo" m CO_ > CO m C« N N f) M H-, en c o *3 u en o 4) bo cS e rt o> •fl h • COsO *e|-sO t>. (U • •^-r^oo oo oo oo "-• O as r-» cooo CO c a) 3 en o oo o »oso 00 • •*£ O; 0_ M M_ M 8 ; W CN t£ CO i-Tvo" o_ ON i*> . CO CO Os COOO Ph co r^ t£ q; CM SO ( n £> H M ■ef O IDIO iC O "eh O as a— O r-^sO OO O CO O 10 O Os CO "el" O CN o SiOOOWONO r^ ■2'S. ,*> r^ rt-oo n io>on Hi i/> t^ Os Os O sO t^» as sO -h ° CO lO CsT sO" t-^ t"^ as h-i CN CN tN o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 2"3 O O O O O O O u -w SOOOOOOO 3 u »*» lO CN CN t^t>.t^CN H^ 0> CN CN CO CO CO 10 * r^.00 as O <-> m co OsOsONO O O O 00 00 00 os as os os *c3 H EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 205 X Pq T3 C *j u J"* PQ Yen 530,000 630,000 1,023,900 2,019,530 2,602,240 t^ so 10 00 SO T3 s 0) u 000 a • ►"_ to n 10 M Total Yen 530,000 630,000 1 ,050,000 2,053,900 2,769,530 TO 't TO TO o_ E c3 O CQ a Yen 530,000 630,000 1,023,900 2,019,530 PO »t PO N "«5 H Yen 530,000 100,000 420,000 1,030,000 750,000 O O O O" TO 00 cd 06 c 'u a TD O 3 i/) en c u • — a t; 1/1 V) 00000 N O O^O i- ^ '"r 1 '^°°- 8 r-^\o vo 0" m 00 H"i ■"*- fO^O >o ►« p) ~ 00 vO* O 2 > CT> O ►» co 4-> 3 O co C o >-. "o a CD a c CO O On On CM CO On CO O CM VO CM_ t£ 0;nO_ ft ■<£ cm" oo" t-^ cm" i^ l-~ t^OO 00 on PS cOnO On On CO CO t-^NO On On CO o\ 00_ w t-C CO Deposits at end of year Yen 1,009,081 5,060,407 4,600,613 6,532,653 5,812,504 00 m N q, CO CM ^ o • mo • t^oo On On a— , 3 cfl Oh O Few 1,250,000 1,250,000 1,250,000 2,500,000 2,500,000 O O O O* IO 1^. 00" T3 3 V £ CU (0 u 3 JO (O 5 Yen 26,073,405 201,066,333 189,243,297 215.759.646 344,416,296 q> oo" 10 no" CO .2* "5 cj V Yen 28,714,414 200,545,322 188,806,977 217,150,457 344.655.827 o\ ON cm" t^ 00 ON c- ON u ■a u H O O >- CM CO OOOOO 00 On On O O X "c3 a CM - CO NO XJ NO NO .*> UOtC Pi ino to I s ; corf CO *n 3 CJ CO &•§ 6 OJ2 U 88 8 O.O. •>> NO CM pN O IO CM M CO C CO t/1 M-00 liO CO .*> cm" CO Pi C7> M r»* cT «o — CO rt-o O O 1-1,2 8 r^«N| ^ to CM I- 8 00 CO S» CM CN1 $5 nO_ CO Ps 10 10 4) >> CJ J2 "c5*o | - M cu 00 I/O 00 g NO •* ^ t^UO Ps CO O 'o cu c cu cu Pl, 13 •« u -O C3 C « O >> CJ CD if) ICIO to UOUO a— 3 03 a as Cm <-> 88 8 O O ^> o"o" Ps O O 10 10 W nN 1* CU CN CO O O OOn EFFECTS ON THE MONEY MARKET 207 c ed 11 u — > a * a a u u ^ c "O q fc g 12'S £8 ■5 « co*l-m<-o-1-COCOCOCOCON 00000000000 ■* t^ n 00 ■* « 00 mo ifivo <^h C f> >-> N 00 O co cOO i-> >-• NO CO r^ N n m 3^ Nrt o^ c* * n 00 OnoO •-" f-00 O f0ff>«0 f» 00 mMO« n NtooN m *t — ■*)■ o^ *$• o o ^t^t^^t 8 coO~ (00"rtNN "1-00 Tf O .*> vO COOO On co On O O 00 •- N >i o>^M 0> moO_ CO N 0_ cOCO_ cO t~»0~o" iOm'iCm NO ■"*• w — N Tj-*3-'*J"'' ! 1" u '5 ,/i,/5u " 5 O N N On in OnO ►< ►"• 00 f~» O0000 ►" tJ- 1-1 O ON t^ N ON vO « O ►"• On m N_ 0_ ►« t~; ■"■"_ ^in«o"inn , t^o in rj- **■ ~ 1 — . coo »- in o O "*• r~» r-» ^00 n moo O n n oo_ in ■»£ co CO "-f «o rf *f 00* (0« 00 •- N COO N Tf On ■"!■ o n mo HMMNNNlO^^'t'f r, _ -x) — coo o> o mo •- o o t>»o m o 1- 1 co «■« m co CO cO O O O ^t - COO__ f;0_ *£ SooininininoN — o coooo t^. m n 00 conoo ►h 00 cooo o 00 o moo_ co ino_ on co r-*.oo" td-Tw O* 00" r-Io" n co co m co ^* m m\Q t^-00 -ti-> *tQO N tON«\0 NO o 00 o m on n -3-0 in t^-o cooo o * N . °. °} * "t 9. 'T o" o> r-~ O* O* *"■ n" n r-". o in 8 vo r-» ■>*• O "*■ 000 N o moo >> O coo n w ino_ c^ n c^o_ " -^ M t-~.vO* O" O" M •-" •-* N rf On O N O O in On "tO r» r-» „ hh n n n onrtn o ON O O On ~t -1- **- On O O O O 0000 N-rt>^0 t^O coO 00 m'tqoo - 1 o_ n o_ in o" «f Ono" O* On On m co r^ N s m m« mo 'i-coooo 1- t~ ,»» co on co tj-oo m n_ ino_ ►« n_ o" •->* 0~ o" o" *> 00 1-" in in - ' i-NNO*t" l - , 00NO — NN „ „ _ p< cocO'i-ininmin co -i- >no t^oo on o — n co c5 OnOnOnOnOnOnOnQOOO t -1 00 X 00X00 00 00 OnOnOnON CHAPTER IV EFFECTS ON INDUSTRIES Following the crisis of 1890, came business depression, which lasted for three years, from 1891-1893. During these three years, the principle of conservation was most carefully followed in every branch of industry in Japan, and no positive plans were adopted for any. Meanwhile, however, Japanese business recovered from the blows of the past, the failures of the previous years were forgotten, conditions favorable to productive power were secured, and the once disturbed state of the business world was remedied. As a result, capital ac- cumulated, the condition of the money market became sluggish and the business people of the country were thus prepared to enter upon fresh activities. But just at this time the Sino-Japanese War broke out, and the nation, putting everything else aside, was compelled to devote its whole energy to the prosecution of the war, which was a life-and- death struggle to Japan. Fortunately for her, Japan won a glorious victory and in- creased her prestige greatly in the eyes of the whole world. People in general were encouraged by this victory to such an extent that the money market, after having met the very large expenditure necessitated during the war, showed reserve power after the war was over. Encouraged by this favorable state of the money market, the enterprise of the people, which had been restrained during the war, suddenly burst forth everywhere in new business undertakings. Of the various branches of business which the minds of the people were thus stimulated to engage in during these years, railways came first, and next banking, while the least enthusiasm was shown for general commerce and industry. A glance at the conditions of industry in Japan during the war shows that while the interference with communication and the money market affected to some extent the general 208 EFFECTS ON INDUSTRIES 209 industries of the country, yet on the other hand the unusual activity apparent in munition factories, occasioned by the need of munitions on the battlefield, balanced this depression. Besides, in those days, most of the industries in Japan were still at the outset of their development, and therefore supply- ing local demands only, so that they did not sustain any very serious blows during the war. Indeed, it may be stated that even during the war industries in Japan, generally speaking, made some progress, and when a business boom set in after the war their advancement was of course still more remarkable. Thus during these years the Japanese laid the basis for the notable progress which their industries attained after the Russo-Japanese War in later years. Let us first look at the conditions of industrial investment in Japan. As we have no authentic materials for a survey of the whole field of in- dustry, we shall tabulate the amount of capital of the com- panies engaged in various industries as follows: Capital Investment in Industry Paid-up capital Year Number of companies Authorized capital Reserve Amount Increase Yen Yen Per Cent Yen 1896. 1.367 I43.6i7.530 89,900,900 100. 7,404,980 1897- 1,881 165,332,633 105,381,106 1 17.2 7.58i,535 1898. 2,164 183,657,046 1 22,066,653 135-8 11,64 1899. 2,253 222,673,634 1 17.; 164.4 13,467,802 1900. 2,554 216,766,903 158,851,730 17" 7 17,697.540 1901 . 2.477 2 l' 1.249,806 K><),2i)3,oi>3 185.O 24,057,360 1902 2,427 222,120,693 1 73, 192.7 24,794.154 1903- 2,441 214,404,088 170,346.340 1895 29,966,661 Tot al . 17.564 1,587,822,333 1,133,845,701 136,613,025 As the figures in the foregoing table indicate, the capital invested in certain industries was doubled in the lour or five years subsequent to 1896, and thenceforward it continued to increase at the same rate. Yet when compared with the amount of capital invested in other kinds of business, 1 it will 1 Cf. table, p. 210. is 210 ECONOMIC EFFE( fS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR be seen that the increase in capital of the companies engaged in these industries was far smaller than that of companies engaged in agricultural and commercial business and in com- munication. The percentage of this industrial investment compared with the total amount of investment in all these different kinds of business, too, was generally less than 20 per cent; so that it may be seen that industrial investment did not increase steadily during said years. In a word, it may be stated that industrial enterprises did not make any consider- able progress during this period. Ratio of Industrial Investment to Total Investment Year Indus- trial com- panies Agricul- tural com- panies Commer- cial com- panies Communi- cation com- panies Total Ratio of industrial investment to the total 1896 . . 1897 . . 1898 . . 1899 . . 1900 . . 1901 . . 1902 . . 1903 . . Per 100 117 135 164 . 176 - 185 192 189 :ent 2 8 4 7 7 5 Per 100 134 141 139 157 159 154 192 :ent 5 8 7 9 Per cent 100. I35-0 155-7 174. 1 201 .9 216.5 228.4 234-4 Per cent 100. 145-5 174.2 I75-0 202.0 214.8 232.0 231.7 Per cent 100. I34-0 1564 172.0 196.0 208.7 221 . 1 223.3 Per cent 22.6 19.8 19.6 21 .6 20.4 10. 19.7 19.2 Of the industrial companies whose paid-up capital is rep- resented in the foregoing table, those having one million yen or more at the end of the year 1903, and making somewhat rapid progress, were the companies engaged in the branches of industry given in the following table. The condition of these companies indicates fairly well the general condition of the business world following the Sino-Japanese War. As the figures in this table indicate, the industries which made most progress during this period were the cleaning of grain, manufacturing of soy bean paste, and tobacco, ship- building, electric light manufacturing, printing, paper mill- ing, and cement manufacturing. All these industries ex- cept tobacco, whose success had a great deal to do with the establishment of the government monopoly system, attained EFFECTS ON INDUSTRIES Progress of Industries, i 896-1903 211 Industry December 31/1896 Grain refining Sake brewing Beer brewing Soy and bean paste manufacturing Sugar refining Tobacco manufacturing Manufacturingof medi- cines and chemicals. . Cotton spinning Other spinning Raw silk Hemp yarn Silk textiles Cotton textiles Hemp textiles Woolen textiles Mining and refining . . . Shipbuilding Railway wheel making Electric light works . . . das works Printing Paper milling Tanning and manufac- turing of leather goods Nets and rods Petroleum boring and refining Cement making. Fertilizer manufacturing December 31. i*99 Yen 344,668 2,056,895 (unknown) 325.392 1,474,106 1, H3.°99 (unknown) 28,770,847 (unknown) 3.869,877 (unknown i 245.355 2,355.178 790,000 814,416 8,585,560 2,272,866 (unknown) 4,624,097 (unknown) 690,067 2,872,793 523.250 668,210 9,500,000 1,330,000 (unknown) 1.2 55.978 6, 1 33.°44 2.756.940' 1 928,460 2,419,968 11,320,965 (unknown) 30,313.054 5.I95.89I 4.547.215 3,066,120* 748.079 3.975.940 (unknown) 2,367,000 10,020,418 5,011,600 (unknown) 7,909,018 2,302,400" 992,061 6,265,095 636,4*5 648,410 14,241,109 4,078,085 660,560 December 31. 1903 Yen i,4<>8,426 3.748,253 3.156,470 1,943.796 2,710,300 13.385.933 2,132,865 32,666,875 7,010,070 4,620,788 1,607,230 2,075,844 1,201,199 1,788,400 1,926,750 10,933,235 10,530,100 1,470,000 12,151,561 5,544,500 1,806,814 8,729,661 1,128,815 1,033,500 4.4')7.743 3.767.374 1,850,462 ise of 190^ [896 Per Cent 435 182 184 1,202 114 119 846 51 226 237 127 463 263 262 304 216 155 47 283 » As of December 31, 1900. their several degrees of progress as a result of the general advance in the conditions of society at large after the war. Let us then note the number of factories in operation, with the number and horse power of machines in use, and we shall see what remarkable progress the totals in the following table indicate. 1 Now let us compute the number of factory hands. Be- tween 1896 and 1906, this was about 430,000, without any considerable change during these years. About 40 per cent 1 Cf. detailed figures given on pp. 221 and 222 relative to the ages and summary of factory hands, etc. 212 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Factories in Operation and Horsepower of Engines Year Number of factories Percentage Number of engines Percentage Horse power Percentage 1893 • • 1894 . . 1895 • • 1896 . . 1897 • • 1898 . . 1899 . . 1900 . . 1901 . . 1902 . . 1903 . . 3.019 5.985 7J54 7.640 7.287 . 7.085 6,699 7,284 7.349 7,821 8,274 1 00.0 198.7 237.0 253- 1 241.4 234 7 221 .9 241.3 243-4 259- 1 274.1 2,080 4,020 4.989 5.459 5.88o 5.172 4.093 3.977 4.551 4,808 5.226 100. 193-3 239-9 262.5 282.7 248.7 196.8 191 .2 218.8 231 .2 251-3 32,811 41.031 61,252 64.429 63.434 79,016 76,885 95,392 91,585 100,901 102,797 100 125 186 196 193 240 234 290 279 307 313 1 7 4 3 8 3 7 1 5 3 of these hands were males, and the remaining 60 per cent females. Considered as to age, 90 per cent of the total number were 14 years or older, and the remaining 10 per cent young hands less than 14 years of age. About 93.4 per cent of the total number of male hands, and about 85.6 per cent of the total number of female hands were more than 14 years of age. From these figures, it may be inferred that the number of young hands (those under 14 years of age) was small among male hands, but comparatively large among female hands, as Table I at the end of this chapter 1 indicates. Of the figures given in the foregoing pages, the most im- portant may be summarized as shown in the table on the next page. As some figures are lacking in the table, we can not make comparison with the time previous to the war. While it is true that during and after the war industrial schemes were started in various parts of the country, yet we must realize that the industrial development attained by the* Japanese during those years can not be called remarkable. Except in the production of half-manufactured articles, an industry which had been developing in Japan even before the war, the progress made during this period was only in those branches of industry devoted to the production of articles for home consumption or those necessitated by the improve- ment in standards of living, but not for export. This may be l Post, p. 218. EFFECTS OX INDUSTRIES 213 Ratio of Capital Invested, Factories and Factory Hands, 1893 No. of factory hands Paid-up capital No. of factories Xo of Year engines power Male Female Total 1893 . . . 100. 100. 1 00.0 (unknown) (unknown) (unknown) 1894 ••• 1895 • • • (unknown) 198.2 193-3 125. 1 (unknown) (unknown) (unknown) (unknown; 2370 239-9 186.7 (unknown) (unknown) (unknown) 1896 . . . IOO. 253-0 1 00.0 262.5 100. 196.4 1 00.0 100. 100. 100. 1897 • ■ • II7- 2 241.4 95- 4 282.7 107.7 190.6 98.5 105-5 97-5 100.7 1898 . . . 135.8 234-7 92.7 248.7 94-7 240.8 122.6 101.7 89-5 94 4 1899 •-.- 164.4 221 .9 87.7 196.8 75-0 234-3 H9-3 86.6 98.0 93 4 1900 176.7 241-3 95-4 191 .2 72.9 290.7 148. 1 88.7 94-9 92.4 1901 . . . 18S.O 243-4 96.2 218.8 834 279.1 142. 1 90.6 98.2 95-2 1902 . . . 192.7 259- 1 102.4 231 -2 88.1 307 -5 1566 106.3 119. 6 H4-3 1903 ■ • ■ 189. s 274-1 108.3 251-3 95-7 313 3 159.6 104.4 1 15 ■ 1 no. 8 seen from the fact that of the total value of exports from Japan to foreign countries in these years, half-manufactured articles were usually 45 or 50 per cent. However, the value of imported half-manufactured articles was between 15 and 20 per cent against about 25 per cent of manufactured articles, while the value of imported manufactured articles was 26 to 30 per cent, although this percentage began gradually falling towards the end of the decade 1 893-1 903. In summing up, it may be stated that while we must admit that after the Sino-Japanese War the Japanese were encour- aged by the favorable economic condition to start various industrial enterprises, these schemes were on rather a small scale. Then, again, the various industries thus started were all for the purpose of supplying domestic needs, and no develop- ment was attained in industries for the production of export articles. Though the glorious victory and the intervention of the Powers hastened the national awakening of tin- Japa- nese people to a great extenl . yet it was >till too early tor any elaborate reorganization of the industrial world. The go's em- inent was too busy with work such a- the administration of state finances, the reform of the currency system, adjustment of the money market, preparation of armaments, etc. A- to 214 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR the people, it was only a short time after the country had been opened to foreign intercourse, and they did not have capital enough to do any work independent of the government. For these reasons, neither the government nor people of Japan could yet lay a firm foundation for the establishment of what may be called an industrial empire in Japan. This they ought to have done as a result of the war, and it is much to be regretted that it was impracticable, because the establishment of an industrial empire is an indispensable requisite in the improvement of international finance. When we consider the elevation in Japan's international position after the war, the maintenance of the gold standard adopted after the war, and the increase in the people's purchasing power which accom- panied the importation of the indemnity from China, we regret this the more. Even at the present time (191 5), about 20 years after the Sino- Japanese War, we have still failed to establish such an industrial empire, hindered especially by the Russo-Japanese War, and this fact alone tells something of the industrial conditions of Japan in those post-bellum years. The State of Industrial Capital The general condition of capital investment in industrial works was briefly set forth in the previous section. We shall now consider the amounts of paid-up capital in the hands of companies engaged in the principal branches of industry. Table II at the end of this chapter 1 gives the figures for the years 1 896-1 903. None of these figures suggest large investments certainly. Industries were started during these years either for the pur- pose of meeting home demands or of laying the foundations for later development, as when Japan might become a leader in the production of articles for export to foreign countries. The State of . Industrial Labor In the statistics published by the Department of Agricul- ture and Commerce as to the condition of industrial factory 1 Post, p. 219. EFFECTS OX INDUSTRIES 215 labor in Japan, figures for 1895 and earlier are lacking, so that we have not the materials for a comparison of the conditions of factory labor before and after the Sino-Japanese War. An investigation of the average number of factory hands employed in industrial work, as furnished in the official statistics published since the year 1896, shows us that about 10 per cent of the whole population of the empire was employed in this kind of labor. See Table 1 1 1 at the end of this chapter. 1 If the factory hands enumerated in Table III are divided into two classes, adult and young, with the age of 14 as the dividing point, we shall find that the adult hands (14 years old or older) are about 90 per cent of the total. See Table IV at the end of this chapter. 2 The proportion between male and female hands is 40 per cent male and 60 per cent female. Although the number of male hands did not increase much during these years, the number of female hands increased somewhat rapidly. Of the male hands, about 94 per cent were adults, while of the female hands, adults formed about 87 per cent of the whole number. Therefore it may be inferred that young female hands were more numerous than male. See Table V at the end of this chapter. 3 Percentages as to average daily wage of adult factory hands in the principal branches of industry (such as flour milling, yarn spinning, manufacturing of textile fabrics, knit- ting, machine making, shipbuilding, furnace working, gas works, paper milling, dyeing, etc.) during this period, as in- vestigated by the Department of Agriculture and Commerce, are given in Table VI at the end of this chapter. 4 Compared with independent workmen such as carpenters, plasterers, etc., the increase in wage appears rather small. As regards the kinds of independent labor given in the table for reference, further notes will be given in Chapter VIII, pages 278-319. These facts clearly show us that the condition of factory hands was generally bad compared with that of independenl 1 Post, p. 220. 2 Post, p. 221. t, p. 222. 4 Post, p. 223. 2l6 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR workmen. Let us now compare the price of factory labor with the prices of commodities. See Table VII at the end of this chapter. 1 As shown by the figures given in Table VII, the prices of commodities rose more rapidly than the wages of factory hands. It is obvious that the rise in the prices of commodities brought about a rise in house rent and other items concerned in the cost of living, and a consequent pressure upon the life of the working class. This wage, low compared with the wage of independent workmen, which rose more rapidly than the prices of commodities, made the position of factory hands very difficult during these years. Let us now investigate the number of hours these factory hands had to work a day. In those days we had no factory law in operation. Then again, factory owners were not farsighted about the management of their factories, nor did they experience any trouble with their factory hands. It is obvious that the latter were forced to work excessively long hours a day — doubtless as much as 12 or 13 hours, although we have no authentic statistics at hand to prove it. This we may infer, however, from the fact that when a 12-hour day clause was inserted in the factory law which was prepared in quite recent years, objection was raised by many of the authorities best acquainted with the condition of factories in Japan. As it was, the appearance of the factory labor class, which had not existed in old Japan, presented a serious question which the leaders of the country were called upon to investigate from the points of view of social customs, public sanitation and the preservation of the family system in the country. In a word, it may be stated that after the Sino- Japanese War, unusual activity was manifested in indus- trial circles in Japan, with a consequent heavy demand for factory hands. This demand for factory labor brought about in some degree an increase in the income of the working class. At the same time, however, as there was no factory system established in those days, the appearance of this 1 Post, p. 225. EFFECTS OX INDUSTRIES 2IJ factory labor class encouraged an undesirable tendency in society, which should be seriously investigated in the interests of public sanitation, health, and morality. In other words, the factory labor class is the most interesting by-production of the industrial developments which followed the Sino- Japanese War. And the appearance of this factory labor class requires the leaders of the country to devise improve- ments in the factory system and the condition of the people of this class, for the sake of the industrial development of the country as well as public sanitation and the health of the people in general. 218 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR W ri c o o l_ Oh © t— *t "* "*" W r ^>°° O O "* cO CN ifl-tO o o a* o cs c^ >-' "-' "<3 O H "<3 o H SO Cs m Cs ■*!" ""> | - 1 C> -< ti-o o) t-~. m as co so m cs o ■+ "5 00 .. 00 .. so" os c)"oo" -< O O >-" OsCO V O >0 CO <0 t^ C Os iO SO O t^sO i-i rt-sO CO Os CO 1/5 t-^sO CO CN_ ■*£ i-T in rf SO 00 t>- W-> SO in CO !0 "3- in i-i O CsiCNCNCsicsiCsitOcO in Pi a a o « o H O <: SO tJ-NsO t^ in N "* in ■*■ coso in i-i c* o SO O sO fsi 00 N_sO_ ** ■N"t csi in so n oo • • • t-» rj- iOsO_ CO ' [ coob" o os cn ^0) •<*• t-^sO sO SO . . • m ** osoo »n '. 1 ; oo'oo t^tnoo" u o -a c .S >. l_ O (J rt "<3 +J O H ■to oooa* (si oo oo m t>. • • • r^co q_ "«£°o ■ inso" t-^ CO CN ' SO SO r-» CO '*■ CO CO CO ■* ^t - E 0) to N O M N H tj-so r^ rj- m • * • ° "i. ^^ '-L ' CO OsO CO Os cs) M N sO sO N « N « « fsi O CssO 00 00 CS) o >i o» • • • sO t^ cO00_00_ ! oTso" O* C> CO 4> > so r>.oo os O <-> c» co OsOsOsOsO O O O OCOOO000 OsOsOsOs EFFECTS ON INDUSTRIES 219 no PO O 00 -r ~ O O r- •* ONNOC q>oo_ o_ rs. tovo* c" O ao \o ►- n p«5nO O O ^ PO 00 pOnO Tj" t^ t^ £ 2 pi 00 nO O O O 00 On »T tC -f rC 1^.nO pOOO p| t»}0C 1^. r<5 PO mO 1^00 "+ r-» tj- po pi \C in po po r^ O \C 00 pO PI O OnOC^ PO inoo" pi in t)-0 O rt pi 1- pOO t» ~ on vO On "+ N IOIO i<)m ir.O r^oo — 00 O \Q PI 0_ i-T ro 0> m 1/500 1/5 On f/N 0_vC_ — in 10 -f >- pO O 00 00 CUD N ■tq;C> 00' On lO PI ~ m On •<*■ PI ci »■« in-ti- m NO UO On ►* onooo n O" «10N PI m On *+■ »_ pi N r^ r-» in nC NO NO if. -t P^ (X c O -+ pO On O (^•-11/31/5 |S, -+ Tt00_ rT -t- ic c pOOO r>. On On pO M On N -f fO o o 1 o ^ o » : -*■ ~ IT, JMT, rOC • C — — ~ — r-^ pi —> IC moo vO ^HtO MO — ""!" — ~ 10 C r i t*J rt ""' -r C r i «!*• «N| On On 1/5 "- "J 00 . '"; M w o" O N "5 — 80 C 00 C M c >o o" «~" I- 10 NO c* tON O OC 1 - 30 — PlOOOmPlPO ir.C'.C — OO— "". ■-1 POOO h N -t|N f^^O. tfl -f t^ O CO r-^o" m «* CnO •tfOiR'ti- ""- !*• 1 ^. p<5 in 00 vO rt ff'00 M M ri no" o" o" -i ~ C - '1 ~ s. OnO ! On PO O On - o POPOOT cT m" o" t-^00" cs >-■ t-. no PO 1- 00 On •*On O" M - o p| O O 00 O 00 « -to ~ Q ~ M CO "t^. - PO 1/5 t~- O ►" On PO t^NO N m o O On PO O O OJ fN P0 fi O "5N M if NO ~ O O C4 in OnnO On N On On On O nO nO o O » O H N 1/5 t^ "+ lO ^t - »0 O 1 O^ PnI t-^ I — t^ 00 00 IN nO OOO ON >- "S" O fN •* M 0" pi O" W5NO" -1- 1^ -to "*■ **} in no" r^vo m ►-> cs in 00 00 "t°_ no" 00" no 1^ •- o 00 ■- On PI 2 $ NO On £5 PI O On o i^- m on in r- vo" 1^ in poo -t mo no — PO no 00 pO o On £ no ^ o PI NO 00 On O NO PO <-> nO_ in rf •>*• PI 1^ -t PO "+ PO on t^ On -r C '- PO o" ■- 1^. ►- 1^ . On bfl c o rt 3 bo bo rt .S.S £ c •- c c vO m r^ po rt NO On POOO i- ■ -* pi_ 0_ r-;- r--. ' o" <> o" in o" ; o onno c h TfrOO PI nO_ cnj" — " in po in 00 m 00 pi m o no" in TtOO 00 nO pi pi po in -r 1- -" o" 00 PI r, — Pl" O Ti- to O OOOOnO N In-vOnD ON 1 « -t inoo_ o_ ' in -t in pi" •+ ' m •- 00 t^ pi ' pooo m pi no t^ PO VO On • o_ t>. ! o" Pl" S 1 ^ ' NO 00 3 : no m po «*• •SB'S 5 Cp" 1 " b03.H P C « V- — -5 tn ~ o 3 g y O — rt u w «J5.a. 5 « c IflvS i x £S^ ■o I :.s| . _ i- _ cj bo • c 2 c.H.S g ci: 5 « aj « t r 2 JS « C n o c~ - L. > <*■ 1 — i o a. a, Pli uh uu. 220 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR bd .5 '33 CD U U c -o c /0r^0 1 '00v0v0 o o^ o^vo *o t-.\o 0000 Tj-mcor^oo in oo" CO O iOvO~ m N cji CM vO 1^ CM ^f- "*■ CO w 1 ^ ( \ cm_ co ■* inccco^ vo" ON cfoo" CO »OOo" CO CO CO i-i O O <-> ON00 tn B 0) Ih o "3 ° o.S H CM cooo co cm t^vO CM m i-i o\\0 O CM cOvO 1^ "2 ^ *£ ""i ^1 "1 lO C?> >0 rCoo"oo" ii CO O oo co O O On cooo tJ-vO On CM its t^- >-i CO h h h N N N n« MNMNNNNN O lOcOcor^O O 1 >0 VO O r^vO i-i Ti-vO CO °1 ^1 "2 ^^ ^1* m to -^-vo'co" rC co "-T VO iO to lO >t T) « O M N N N « N tOtf) in 2 u o 3 ° 3.5 H w (NOO COIOIOO ON lO^O !0 0>Nt)-0 co ■* t? r^ t-C co n~vo" CM NtOH cO-3-O co 00 O cOvO On CM vO 00 wNCMCMCMCOCOCO Ct««(H«(H«M u >- ^ 03 VO t)-MvO r^. iO CM rh lO Tt- cOvD «m NO vO_ CM_vo_ CM_oq_ NO rf ■* tf rC h-T rf oo" »o cm" t^oo t^- io wo moo oo Id vO t^OO ON O ii CM CO O^On^OO o o o 00000000 On On On ON O CO Si o u 3 o a u2 (LI U 5^ J3 c c - cd M O c rt «j 01 .fija ,-i w ■* v R 4) tf ~ ~ OJ u c >>-o V ja u rt -1 ui >i -i s = u ^ -1 c Ti it c a 3 c & 3 ■a Q B O - e,j3 ^ s «j .ce ^ " u - - V " - — *j •- H a. a in H p u EFFECTS ON INDUSTRIES 221 Percentage compared with total — C o .g bo C O § -t « to « »n S" " O 00 Cv <~ooo c M M t3 a) c "3 — < ■— CO On ON00 ©\ in C a 1- Cl *<3 C 3 > u O (J (d "rt O H > m ~t m rr> o r, o o r- i~0\O ^ * " cf vO oo" »o o o 6 o £ m r>. o r*» "*■ O fN ")vO CS 00 c : ; *~: "t l/ ? - *2 ^ " * ccoo" O* Cv Ct C rO 01 ro •«*■ to o o oonooN g . - iO i-i ooo_ lO ^j> " ~ oo'oo" t-^ ICOO* c <-> u _o "o u o • -t- w C M 'c o o [x, "c3 o H c -t; ooo ai > NXOO lOh. r^oo o_ ^oo_ c : ; in o" r^ ro ri 1 ~ 3 5 u (Unknown) 223,042 220,160 226,771 263,642 "3 c c» 00 00 '-; 00 M O - r i O ^ ^ r ? 00 . 00 . c : c ri" 0" 0" c^ 00 B m w w w « vO f^oo r C M N rO j 3 O O O 00 00 00 oc 5 3 222 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR "rt k o r- -t- tj- ■+ n coco O V. O O ^0^3\3*H i-i u e3 rt &H o Pi 4) K o i^NO r»0 CO •<*• a ^ o m~^o co o^o ** s ^ OOO00 00 o^oo ^ „ H M •M 5?. E -a *- ^t 00 00 00 00 00 cd fe <£ o !- C^ o b .- o i- is o a o •« c Cu s ^-^ OS C\ O OOn ^ c s S o « C\ OwO OCO CO U OOOifl N« m N N *- \0 >/5 10\0 VO O O VO g-2 fe fti — o ^ £ c 800\w«*«NN a*~ cd "° O « MN0OO0 t^ (^ o 2 ^ "^•'^•''I-COCOCOCOCO Oh fin U c 4 > VO t^OO 0\0 -N to ONOnOOOOOC 000000O0 tj\ *C o 00 \c r- - O -*00 o •+• O i-> X -t- <0 t^» C •- cr ? ' a ;^ .0 i a a 57 c = .2 r™ M r 1-lL 00 m five ft Is S-S 9 5 c ■- e - <^5 gc tf u 3 — C O 1^-tiO i> « 8 • 2* — 00 e 2 T ~t f*i30 g g a, 4) > - - to <3 ~~ o PU cr. c « - vO O M M M M -* O O O IO ON r : 2 r c — — — — ■- M O Nil C300 u > 100 10 >o c < tn : -t- § : 5 O O O L. - >< (3>0 -N (1 ^OOOO 00 c* r" M M M M M CHAPTER V EFFECTS ON COMMERCE The ill effects that the commerce and trade of Japan in general suffered from the Sino- Japanese War were compara- tively small. Although the interruption in transportation by land and water caused by the transporting of troops and civilians in connection with the war (amounting to 300,000) interfered with the supply of necessary merchandise for a short time, resulting in a subsequent rise in prices, yet these difficulties were soon removed; especially as the government paid careful attention to the money market and as conditions were favorable to Japan all through the war, the Japanese Navy having complete control over the China Sea. For these reasons Japan's trade with America and Europe was rather more prosperous than before and trade with China and Korea did not suffer much. In order to show the state of commerce and trade in general during the war, we shall now call atten- tion to the table on the following page which gives the amount of negotiable paper handled, the notes cleared, and the present general condition of the country's foreign trade during these years. As we see from the figures, neither the volume of commerce at home nor that of foreign trade decreased ; indeed there was more or less increase in each case. While it is true, as just stated, that during the war no adverse effects were suffered by trade in general, yet after the war important effects were more apparent. The minds of the Japanese people in general were decidedly stimulated, for as the fruits of the war Japan obtained an indemnity of 200 million taels in Chinese Kuping silver, and the concession of the Island of Formosa. Enthusiasm for business enterprises speedily developed among the people, and this, coupled with the government's post-bellum program, created unusual activ- 224 EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 225 Negotiable Paper and Foreign Trade During War Period 1893 [894 1895 Notes handled by Tokyo associated banks: Receipts Yen 71,234,966 100,467,393 Yen 85,203,203 103,144,795 Yen 98,809,120 137.943.935 Notes handled by Osaka associated banks: 44,033,992 66,320,081 46,981,007 82,863,147 64,438,604 102,981,074 Expenditures Negotiable paper handled by Tokyo Clearing House: Amount presented Amount cleared 188,591,742 148,018,870" 227,767,017 i85.597,502 b 356,841,068 289,102,425° Negotiable paper handled by Osaka Clearing House: 63,600,661 67,543,806 79,654,118 Foreign Trade: China and Korea: 9,015,663 19,095,414 57.933.054 46,4s j, 956 1 1 , 1 79,099 19,694,820 7*1,825,062 67,608,724 12, 966, 586 25,910,544 94.327.59o 75.543.047 Europe and America: Imports Total 177,970,038 220,728,042 265,372,754 » 78. s per cent of amount presented. ; per cent of amount presented. 81. 1 per cent of amount presented. ity in business. In addition to the importation of cash with such great purchasing power as the indemnity from China, there was a large infirm of foreign capital as a result of the adoption of the gold standard for the country's currency system. Various kinds of enterprises were therefore started in all parts of the country and carried on by means of the financial facilities afforded by a special form of bank, the immovable property banks, which the government insti- tuted after the war. These all overcame the various diffi- culties that beset the money market after the war, and, without occasioning any serious hindrance to commerce in general, brought about an entire change in the conditions of commerce and trade from those obtaining before the war. 16 226 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Table I at the end of this chapter 1 is illuminating in this connection. These statistics do not cover all of the items concerned, yet give some idea of the general conditions of commerce and trade after the Sino-Japanese War. Let us now investigate the subject of capital employed by the companies engaged in commerce and trade since 1896. The percentage of increase in the paid-up capital of these companies was far greater than that in the capital of com- panies engaged in such business as agriculture, industry and transportation by land and water. And of the various branches of commerce and trade the most highly developed during these years were money lending, warehousing, in- surance, sugar, fishery and marine products, raw cotton, cotton yarn, raw silk, textile fabrics, publication and sale of books and newspapers, etc., timber and lumber trading, sale and purchase of immovables, and banking. Each of these branches of commerce made progress in consequence of the general development of the country which followed the war. Let us first examine the outstanding facts as to the capital in- vested in commerce during this period, as given in Table II at the end of this chapter. 2 While the figures just given represent only a portion of the commercial agencies in existence, yet from these figures we may judge the general condition of commerce during these years. To explain this unusually rapid development, we may mention (1) the starting of various sorts of enterprises by the government as well as private individuals after the war, (2) the increase in the purchasing power of the people, especially the lower classes, resulting from the monetary gifts and other payments made them for their services in the war, and also from the greater demand for labor of this period. This increase in the people's purchasing power naturally brought about a rise in the prices of commodities, and an excess of imports over exports in the country's foreign trade. In the following pages we shall further examine the effects of the 1 Post, p. 239. 2 Post, p. 240. EFFECTS ON COM M I k< I 227 war upon the domestic commerce and foreign trade of the country. Domestic ( < >m m i r< i Domestic commerce in general That during and after the Sino-Japanese War domestic commerce in Japan did not suffer seriously in any way, but rather attained to a more healthy development, was brie In- stated in the foregoing section. Let us now consider the same subject in a little more detail and from various points of view. Let us, first of all, note the condition of the money market, as presented in Table III at the end of this chapter. 1 The figures show us that as soon as business began to re- cover from the effects of the war, the supply of capital in the market became liberal, which fact indicates the general condition of commerce during these years. Next let us investigate the buying and selling of merchandise, which always promptly reflects commercial conditions. Below are given statistics as to the volume of goods carried by railways, although the goods carried were not for domestic commerce only. Volume of Goods Transported by Railways* State railway s Private railway s Total Vear Tonnage I'l-r. entage of incn 1893 1894 1895 [896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Tons 1 ,<>;(, ,(,S(, 1,018,298 1 , 1110,059 1,266,119 1,558,194 1.793,896 2,391.471 2,806,560 J. (..S9.602 3.1 83,720 3,492,622 Tons 2,41 4.394 3.265,404 4.23L353 5.579.1 12 7.070,315 8,122,230 9,428,563 1 [,594,960 1 [,750,150 [2,938,951 1 (.,268,690 Tons 3,491,083 4.283,702 5.33 '.4 1 - 1 6,845,231 8,628,509 9,916,] ji. 1 1 ,820,03 \ 1 \. |"I ,520 ' 1,409.752 [6,122,67] 17.701,312 100. 122.7 [52.7 iwi. 1 •'17 - 1 vvS.6 412.5 412 461 508.8 Total... . 22,347,230 90,664,122 1 [3,011,352 » Prepared and published by Imperial < .ova anient Railwaj - 1 Post, p. 241. 228 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Again let us investigate those branches of business upon which a tax was levied in accordance with the Business Tax Law 1 promulgated in March, 1896, and enforced on January 1 of the following year. Since this law has been in force only from 1897, we have no authentic materials for comparison with conditions prior to that year, especially from 1893 to 1896, yet the statistics given below doubtless furnish materials from which we may ascertain the true condition of commerce during these years. The business tax of the law referred to was imposed upon 24 different forms of business, but we shall confine ourselves to the sale of commodities. The standards for rating the tax were three, viz., (a) the total value of the merchandise sold during the previous year, (b) the average rent of buildings in the previous year and (c) the maximum number of employes engaged in the business in the year previous. The figures are shown in Table IV at the end of this chapter. 2 According to the law referred to, the business tax was imposed upon such persons, engaged in business, as sold merchandise to the value of 1,000 yen or more a year. Al- though the law states that the tax was to be levied in accord- ance with said triple standards, in reality it was not, because of the many difficulties attending the application of such a law. The figures prepared by the tax collectors and given in the preceding table do not of course indicate the total amount of the commercial transactions of the country during this period, yet assuredly they do give some idea of the general commercial conditions of the time. From these it may be inferred that the development of Japanese commerce during said years was comparatively great. Of course it must be remembered that the said business tax was first levied after the war, when the country's commerce had attained considerable progress. While we regret that we have no authentic written materials from which to ascertain the state of commerce previous to the war, especially during the years from 1 893-1 896, and also that we can not give here 1 Law No. 33. 2 Post, p. 242. EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 229 the exact commercial development that Japan made since that time, yet considering the economic development effected both before and after the war, it is reasonable to infer that during the same period the country made considerable progress in commerce, too. Table V at the end of this chapter 1 will show the state of capital of the various kinds of important commercial com- panies. From the data given above it may be concluded that during and after the Sino-Japanese War, Japanese commerce did not suffer any reverses, but even made some progress. Trade between Japan proper and the colonies The colonial history of Japan began with the acquisition of Formosa and the Pescadores, which were ceded to her by China as a result of the Sino-Japanese War. The area of the new possessions is 2,324.11 square miles for Formosa, and 7.99 square miles for the Pescadores, making a total of 2,332. x square miles (391.5 square ri) or about 9.4 per cent of the total area of the Empire before the acquisition of these pos- sessions — 24,794.36 square ri. These islands extend from the tropical to the sub-tropical zone, and abound in valuable resources, especially in those products in which Japan proper is wanting, and thus their effect upon the market in Japan is favorable in many respects. Let us examine the statistics relating to the trade between Japan proper and Formosa since the acquisition of the latter island, as given in the table on the following page. Of all the favorable effects that the possession of the island of Formosa has had on domestic commerce in Japan proper, the most striking has come from her production of sugar. Before our acquisition of Formosa, we had to import most of the sugar consumed in our land from foreign countries, but since we acquired Formosa, there had been a gradual change, and now Formosa not only supplies all the sugar consumed in Japan, but even exports the excess of her production to foreign 1 Post, p. 243. 230 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR markets. The sugar industry in Formosa will be treated in detail in the following section. Trade between Japan and Formosa, i 897-1 903 Year Exports from Japan proper to Formosa Imports into Japan proper from Formosa Excess of ex- Value Percentage of increase Value Percentage of increase ports over imports 1897... 1898. . . 1899. .. 1900. . . 1901 . . . 1902. . . 1903. . Yen 3,723J2i 4,266,768 8,011,826 8,439,033 8,782,258 9,235,290 11,194,788 100. 114. 6 215. 1 226.6 235-8 248.0 300.6 Yen 2,014,648 4,142,778 3,650,475 4,402,110 7,345,956 7,407,498 9,729,460 100. 205.6 181. 2 218.5 364.6 367.6 482.8 Yen 1,619,074 123,990 4,36i,35i 4,036,923 1,436,302 1,827,792 1,465,328 Foreign Trade General condition of foreign trade As mentioned heretofore, the Sino-Japanese War, in which Japan won a great victory over China, awakened the Japanese people to a realization of the striking progress which they had achieved since the time of the Restoration (1868). The Japanese so awakened strove for further progress after the war, and naturally, unusual activity in the economic world followed. In consequence, the foreign trade of Japan, of which we propose to treat in the present section, could not but feel the effect of this general tendency. Before the Sino- Japanese War, foreign trade was quite insignificant, but after the war, striking progress was made in the volume of mer- chandise, scope of the market, and total value of exports and imports. The statistics given below show the average annual value of exports and imports for every five years since the first year of Meiji (1868). A glance at these shows us that during the period from 1868 to 1893, or just before the out- break of the war, the largest annual figure for exports and imports attained was 80 million yen while in most of the years of the period it was 20 or 30 million yen, which means 30 or 40 EFFECTS OX COMMERCE 23I per cent of the value of the trade in the year 1893. In none of the years of this period did the value of exports and imports exceed 100 million yen, but after the year 1894 it exceeded 100 million yen and in 1897 it reached 200 million yen, creating a record in the trade history of Japan. See Table VI at the end of this chapter. 1 As the figures in Table VI show, our foreign trade made unusual progress after the Sino-Japanese War, but that prog- ress can not be regarded as accidental. It was a natural outcome of the steady economic development which had been in progress since some time before the war, a result of the development of the latent power of the nation. The statis- tics in Table VII at the end of this chapter 2 show the state of our foreign trade for a period of ten years, beginning before and continuing after the war. While, it may not be correct to say that increase in our foreign trade after the Sino-Japanese War was entirely brought about by the war, nevertheless, there can be no doubt that the war marked a stage of great development in the economic world, then just ready for such development, and that this development brought about progress in the foreign trade of the country. Let us now consider the state of our foreign trade in the ten years following the war. During that period both exports and imports increased about equally, as the figures in Table VIII at the end of this chapter 8 show; the value of exports was doubled in 1898, and trebled in 1902, while tin- import trade advanced even faster, being doubled and trebled a year or two earlier than the export trade. Thus our foreign trade, as indicated by value <>l exports and imports, advanced greatly year by year, especially after the war. And this progress was largely due t<> the increase in the national strength discernible during, and particularly after, the war. Thus among the numerous causes which brought about the advance in foreign trade, we may mention (1) commercial activity, arising from the starting of various 1 Post, p. 244. 2 Post, p. 245. i Post, p. 232 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR kinds of enterprises and development in systems of trans- portation on both land and water; (2) the importation of the indemnity from China; (3) the opening to trade of such ports in China as Shashih, Chungking, Hangchow, and Soochow, in addition to those already opened as a result of a Sino-Japanese peace treaty; (4) increased demand for arms and other munitions during and after the war 1 ; (5) the Japanese ac- quisition of commercial supremacy in Korea; (6) increase in the income of the people, especially those belonging to the lower classes; (7) the reform in the currency system, which removed anxiety caused by frequent fluctuations in the ex- change rate, and favorably affected trade; (8) the abolition of the export duty, which helped to extend the market for Jap- anese goods ; and (9) the revision of commercial treaties with other countries, so long desired by the Japanese Government and people, which laid a firm foundation for the future com- mercial development of Japan. About the time of the Sino-Japanese War, the standard of our currency system, as a matter of fact, was silver, and we suffered considerably from its steady depreciation. Since 1873 (6th year of Meiji) the Powers one after another adopted the gold standard for their currency system, putting a limita- tion on the making of silver coins, and the price of silver gradually fell. In the United States attempts were made to secure a rise in the price of silver by the Brand Silver Purchase Regulations, 1878, and the Sherman Silver Purchase Exten- sion Regulations, 1890; but the general world tendency was against silver, and the United States Government abolished the said silver purchase regulations in 1 893. India, too, stopped the unlimited coinage of silver. Consequently the price of silver quickly fell, and while before 1872 it was generally quoted at 60 d., i.e., the ratio of the value of gold to that of silver was 1 to 15^, it fell to 35A d. or 1 to 26^ in 1893. As silver was practically the standard for the Japanese currency system, the fall in the prices of silver placed Japan in a com- paratively favorable position in her trade relations. For 1 Were needed after the war for the replenishment of arsenals, etc. EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 233 the fall of silver meant a fall in its price as compared with that of gold, and thus Japanese coins became cheaper than those of countries where gold was the standard. Now China with other Oriental countries, which are the principal markets for Japanese goods, adopted the silver standard, and thus Japa- nese coins, in competition with the coins of European and American countries with the gold standard system, won in these Oriental markets, and thus in the point of export busi- ness in the Orient Japan was in a better position than any of the countries with the gold standard. Now the excess of ex- ports over imports in Japan's foreign trade during the period from 1 882-1 889 was due to the said condition of Japan's trade with these Oriental countries. On the other hand, however, frequent fluctuations in the price of silver brought about sim- ilar fluctuations in quotations on exchange rates, and caused great anxiety to traders, for in the home market any fall in the value of coins 1 means a rise in the prices of commodities. Besides, increase in the volume of currency in circulation after the war brought about a further rise in the prices of commodities. This created a situation beneficial to import trade. Despite the benefit which the fall in the price of silver gave to Japan in her trade with Oriental countries, it was not easy to decide whether the silver standard was advisable for the country after all. Finally, the government, disregarding the immediate minor losses which it might incur, adopted tin- gold standard on October 1, 1897. And this reform to no small extent laid the foundation for the healthy progi which the foreign trade of Japan has made ever since. Something must be said here about the revision of the rate of import duty and the abolition of the export duty. For- merly the tariff rates originated in Japan's treaties with dif- ferent countries. Her first tariff rates were concluded with five countries, viz., England, the United States, France, Russia and the Netherlands in 1858 (5th year of Ansei), and revised in 1866 (2d year of Keiwo). According to the treaties 1 A fall in the price of silver, when this i> the material for the unit coin, is always accompanied l>\ a similar fall in the unit of value. 234 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR concluded in 1858, the export duty was 5 per cent ad valorem, and the import duty was from 35 per cent (maximum) to 5 per cent (minimum) . In case it was not mentioned specially in treaties, it was decided at 20 per cent. But after the revision of 1866, both export and import duties were each 5 per cent ad valorem. The import duty was imposed in accordance with the prices of the articles to be taxed, at the port where they were shipped. Now in those days the Japanese were not very familiar with the prices of foreign articles, so the prices upon which the import duty was imposed at Japanese ports were in reality far from the real prices of these articles at the port whence they were shipped. So, although the import duty was fixed by treaty at 5 per cent ad valorem, in reality it was in most cases less than 1 per cent ad valorem. During the period from 1889 to 1899 the average rate of import duty imposed was only 3.985 per cent. On the other hand, articles exported from Japan in those days were not as a rule special products of the country, so that there was no way of shifting the export duty, and the imposition was entirely confined to the Japanese exporters. Thus before the revision of 1899, the Japanese tariff always benefited foreign traders, but was a bar to export trade from Japan. So revision was carried out, and the revised tariff law l was promulgated in 1 897 and enforced on January 1, 1899. The rates of duty upon taxable imported articles were fixed in the revised law at from 5 per cent (mini- mum) to 40 per cent (maximum). Applying these rates to the articles imported during the year 1895, you will see that the rate of import duty thus realized would be on the average 12.35 P er cent. Apply again the conventional tariff rates in the revised law to those articles signified in the treaties between Japan and England or Germany for the conven- tional rates, and you will get an average rate of 10.052 per cent for the same year. Compared with the average rate of 3.98 per cent of import duty previous to the revision, these new rates are far higher. Then, on the other hand, the export duty was entirely abolished on July 17, 1899, and the articles 1 Law No. 14. EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 235 exported from Japan were freed from the imposition of a duty of 3.574 per cent, as the average export duty was during the period from 1889 to 1899. This greatly helped the develop- ment of home industries, on the one hand, and, on the other, served to extend our foreign trade. . The fact that our foreign trade has made remarkable progress since about 1899 was largely due to the revision of these import and export rates. Just here we must say a few words about the successive excesses of imports over exports in our trade after the Sino- Japanese War. A glance at the state of our foreign trade since 1893, just before the war, shows that, except 1894 an d 1895, each year has so far always seen an excess of imports over exports. This excess indeed reached 83 million yen in 1890, which was about 40 per cent of the total value of exports. 1 A glance at the state of our foreign trade from the first year of the Meiji Era shows us that up to 1881 imports always ex- ceeded exports, but in 1882 the condition suddenly changed and exports exceeded imports, and this state continued till 1893. Then, however, imports again exceeded exports. To explain this balance, which has long been in favor of imports as against exports, numerous reasons may be given. But first of all it may be stated that the inconvertible notes which were in circulation in Japan in the early part of the Meiji Era began to be adjusted in 1881; in 1886 the government es- tablished the convertible note system, and the prices of commodities were then brought to a normal state in conse- quence. Before the revision of the currency system, the standard for Japanese currency was silver, so that any fall in the price of silver in those days no doubl benefited exports rather than imports in Japan. But after the war tin- govern- ment revised the currency system, adopting in 1897 the gold standard. Thus she lost the benefit that she had been 1 In 1898 the excess of imports over exports reached about 1 12 million yen, but this must be regarded .is ail exception, for a large amounl of anticipated import orders was received in that year, in view of the enforcement of the revised tariff law in the following year. 236 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR obtaining from the silver standard, i.e., her advantage over gold-standard countries in export trade. Besides, she also incurred losses and inconvenience in the silver-standard countries as well. Then the volume of currency in circulation, which was swelling even. at the time of the war, did not de- crease, but rather increased after the war, because of business activity resulting from the various enterprises started by both government and people. This increase in the volume of currency in circulation caused a considerable rise in the prices of commodities. Then the receipt of the war indemnity from China, the importation of foreign capital, and the increased demands for foreign-made articles, as a result of the advance in the people's style of living, brought a large amount of foreign capital into Japan at a time when the country's power of manufacturing export articles did not greatly in- crease. Moreover, with the various kinds of enterprises started both by the government and the people after the war, the country, which had been exporting mainly raw materials, was now about to become an industrial power. These various reasons taken together were responsible for the continuous excess of imports over exports, which was still a feature of our foreign trade in 191 5, when this book was prepared. Having given, as we believe, a true though brief summary of the condition of our foreign trade after the Sino- Japanese War, we shall now briefly investigate in the following pages the facts as to articles either exported from or imported into Japan in these post-bellum years. Commodities exported and imported As already briefly stated, during the Sino-Japanese War our foreign trade did not suffer seriously from the war, but rather made healthy progress, as the total value of exports and imports increased. Not only did the commercial policy of the government not interfere during the war with general trade but in fact it brought about some development in our trade with China and Korea, even while the war was in progress, as the following statistics show : EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 237 Trade with China and Korea, 1893- Exports -1895 China Korea Year Value Percentage Ratio to the total Value Percentage Ratio to the total 1893 1894 1895 Yen 7,714,000 8,814,000 9,135,000 100. 114 3 118. 4 8.6 7-8 6-7 Yen 1,301,000 2,365,000 3,831,000 100. 181. 8 248.5 1 . 1 2 . 1 2.8 Imports 1893 1894 1895 17,096,000 17,512,000 22,985,000 100. 102.4 134 4 19.4 14.9 17.8 1,999,000 2,183,000 2,925,000 100. 109.7 146.3 2-3 2.3 Consequently, Japanese exports to these countries were all in a favorable state, the principal of these exports being matches, cotton yarn and cotton manufactures. Scarcely less favorable was the state of our trade with Europe and America. With development in our home in- dustries and a better understanding of the conditions in Japan compared with those in European and American countries, the volume of our exports to these countries in- creased. On the other hand, progress in our home industries and advance in the standard of our civilization increased the demands in Japan for foreign-made articles, and our im- port trade also became very active in consequence. The statistics for sundry exports and imports, whose value reached about 3 million yen each at the end of 1893, are set out in Tables IX, X, and XI at the end of this chapter. 1 As these tables show, the principal exports during these years were raw silk, tea, copper, coal, matches and cotton yarn, while the principal imports were raw cotton, rice, Hour, kerosene oil, iron, sugar and woolen manufactures. In 1 Post, pp. 247-253. 2; V S IXONOMK I.IM.< IS OF THE SINO-jAPANESE WAR a word, it may be stated that the Japanese were buying foreign-made articles for their own consumption by selling abroad raw materials or half-manufactured articles, but neither case includes these passing articles of trade. EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 239 CO vb -)- rn r^ CM 00 M '1 1 - 10 J^ vO VO M Ov r^. •- 00 r^ -r - >o Oj o_ 00_ • ■ U] -f t^ 1 - ' .- ~ -t "t '0 q co J£ VO C co r-~ m ; ; «vT CO vO OvvO CO n m 1 - 00 to . . r l lO O CO « Ov lO O CO CO ov >-i ^°, pi M_ 0> q OvO_ ** »^ in « vO 1-1 rj ,_7 06" Pi" _r CO O^vo" tC " : - 0^ tC vO* VO pi Ov co rO 10 " r j c 00 M O "3 00 N CO CM PI PI co vO ja \r t^OO ovoo PI Ov OOvO "I Ov >c - O r> IO Ov (N "~ -t- Ov ri ri 1^ Pv! 1^ 1^ <*• N Tt cn q_ t~; o_ M HH •t-t- c_ 1- 00 h* s 0" r^ 10 -."-to O" CS N 0" . OvvO vO O' rC O" v\> CV| cs" pi" O N Ov ^ \r > CO Pv1 Ov C ) O Ov 100 ►1 vO 1^ 00 ^ ". vq fs. 1H I-~ C ) o_ 00 vo_ o_ u; c<; M CS CO v cf v « 0" 6 ri & ^iCts vO* O lO 00 j> vo « cs 00 00 <* CO >-> l-c vO n fi vO PI CVl PI (N O OOO -t- vOO N O vO PI 00 r> NO m M O M — C ) VC vO l>. CO 00 vO 9. °. M _ "- <■-; rs. 00_ COOO q 00_ w O CO S 00 O PI r^vO r* 5 00' CO coo" -i 00' N t> O" Ov > c . t , c c v— 'J2 c 0) bC Z Z c b b c/> C3 XI * "SI E °u a a c 'u ! c ' c _o O I C r c c - ! -1 c •5 ~v2 ccj ~Z c ) 1 £ c ) u O lashi ki omestic banks. 1_ e i e ! -a — c c a u E- 1 c ; « ff i 1 1 a c T CJ 3 f '. 1 1 3 t 2 - 5 § •- i a u « y ° P3 * e 5^ 5 1 1 >• a £ 01 blic (Kashii of Japan, d 1 associated J j | 1 ) ■> i c a. cd 1 — 1 "o c E -~~- i 'S. a;oi i C3 5 |£ ■3 P — *- 3 £ 1 ^ O C3 O : _ \ i = ~ t _ 1 5 "? renc ard ove atic c > £; W PQHC ) c BOS 1 O c j e 3 J 3 ,c 3 «■ 3 a >■>■'- . v- 30 O. C '53 ' E r &- c ; = - 'J Z L j tfriacori: ** ' -" - u ~ — — — •OT3 « - K S "5 'j D 111)3 > > _ _ : o O+J B C Jj u u u _ - — ir "J J ro ufj Oi — - - X y - c ™ . — u — ' I - ■ 1 I ■- V 9 II - - > J - > > a C 3 — ^ ^:^ 24O ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR I -)-vO O cooC COO -t rO co « O N C> CI O 4> 1^ -tOO (^Nh CO CH S MlC cOOO N N m M C t^OO -J- O t>. t~- O t^ in 3 aid ^, rtN ir,ir,vO ■+ 1000 •"Too" 00" "i-oo" »o c> 0" ^O tJ- "+\0 \ONO« i OOt^OCt^i-rO C/3 cfl .a O 'tvO O vO 00 — co O O co >o s O ci (N rt to H HH HH HH HI l-C ci ci CI a S E | , 'S mica rans ion) nies 0>oc» O >- cO cO 5° ■a e HH HH H. H- C) C| O CI ^ u ^ D- en 3 3 — U3 O 0 •hj-vO to ci on rt ca ^ a O h-. co^O 1^00 O00 a> TJ g "S.S £"0 3 O >— ' CJ c 3° 03 t/> 3 "3 0100 000 so w 3 -3 rt n-HH oci ^-i-ci O O0 N ro^O 6 < N O'dlOI^N C " OvO O cooo m -ti^ h-. CI rOrOcO^Tt-Tj- *o d^C CT> «-i Cv^tONI^- HH r^ N t^.00 >0 HH CO 1*1 t^ CI •<*■ co S co •sJ-OO 3 <-> hh" n o" N O M 0> 0" < O w Nt^ONtOi€ CO rj- Th 10 vO vD vO VD 8 u "3 NO 00 ONI^cO"0U0 a> c t^COf^HH C>CI CI IO if f^vO hh \Q hh ro cooo M f, ^t - 'J- ifl tO lO f) zg u c3 OJ >H vO (^00 Cn O — (S co C\CnOnCnO O O O 00000000 OO^^Ci EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 24I < — vc oc -*■»/; r^-c i- ". ir. : vO C — f. n t^ n -j-x ; 1 - C A — f. *t IA fl N C 1^ C - Z rt -f- 9 1 » O «*J » c;v£: — ir, N "t C 00 *d" >- r*j C "- vC Nf/C O I» rC X x fi iC — ~ W r-» m so_ m_ C£ : rf rC 00 cf *f 1/SvO 1 QtOM/)M •+ C *d-C . «d-^C f^N- m7 242 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR u. ^ E g- 3 E > > 0> 0) -t-X mx ci -t « rCvO i<)m h I ^ CO CI ^" ON 0> X O » O » H ir; 1/"; m-o vO o o»n:t: OvO « re « — 00 CO 00 t^ -}- 10 CT^ ci moo m co 8 O -t rC rC re m ."- ^ o 000 o O ^.rtflM O ON O ►-■ 1/JNlO \o 100x0 ci f i u ? , ? H . h !. H . £ fo n cS i-T t^ o" K ^ ^o m reoo 10 Tt- »—i -. + IT; to 10 H 10 cf vo vo" c^ 10 ox o « h « 10 tj-io 10 10 10 O N Nm mO ci ""; c^ <*j C^ C OvN CT* (^ "- 1 00 — -t IT, fC C\ N .. rdoo" w kTvo* cf 8 f)M n reoo CI . ~ X_ -T t>- -+ rO t~; &\C^C « •*• C — CI rn ^^0000 xx c\jvo^o< EFFECTS OX COMMERCE 243 o> po ~ 1/1 —. O r- *i r- m r r. — 1/} 0^ 00 00 to 000 T T t : t Or- po -O" O \> O in cc N t- — >r ifl -r -T r CO. a * -. m N «t "3 K. *1- O 00 *r m "^ ■* Oi PO N po ro 't C 1- c NO PO po PO 0. O r~ r c O "O q O Cm 00 PO * ft r ro z <- r~ O in rt MM PO N N PO O M PO 10 ci _^^ ON -i - O m r- K — 1- ■: - c r- r> -1 O CO ON O* O O T to ~^. c c 00 O ■■■ c o> -PJ- PO g m r- -t» c f: •o- — . « to -r -. c x. m t~ t^ O 01 »» i-Io" -1 DO -r in m C ro 1- "i 00 00 t> 9 in -r in *~ n o> Tfuic r» <* m ro « w. -r O. mo , -1 - - ~; ir 1- LT O O PO -0 0. ■* PO t^ m — q O m *i n n T PO 1 — N N t 10 - PO PO ■pj- « O m in moC , r O — - : PO O — •- 000 0. 00 r* n po s. do : r - - N N m Oj CI M in DO B«< 00 o_ -r s. r-oo r^ O o> st O in r- po DC N ro r" — N 00* r^oo i- c O « „ kjoo- T m Ot C'- t - in r~ Pi t— po Cioc m m O so -< 00 ^f ": x . PO *t q -f i-<" N G1 p et -t 1^ r> - 00 10 ro _ « O00 ^r S. — M 3 in ^■ro in m 01 Tt« Tj" O « N ro S* t^ n m z - s. - moo Umoo O O n m POX J-. z so O St 00 •-" r— r-cc *-> O I - T - -T O m « rt z -' m ^* ^010 -0 "- &r*CA 00 po r- *~ in >i in m r-o O PO 00 s. r-uiN O. po po r~ o_ in h W ■- N POO O IH — — PO m PO O t t~ O O M in 0. O r~ O r^ r^ n in m •■h 00 ^t N Oi JC O.00 u> Ooo : - 00 00 O. r* 10 f) 5 DC -. c . '" in in -r m c' - a Oi 00 St rooo* 6" 0" O* — c' vl 1^ - ■» ♦» mo Ov PO 1- * -0 <- r- i~ - z po m -r >iX n in 00 C O t^- N - "■ s. 1 - -r - q 10 _T <-■ ~T •1 IOO 00 N N in t^. O N q c 00_ N o_ in MM PO _r pi -1 ~> T 0" N OO m O O t^ IT CO O -r - -O - O m N Oi Ov «-" go [ 00 in • O r~oo 10 s. O. t ". N . ^P. " BO O ■ o_ 9. ° o_ 00 ? 0" PO in O »•" .*> t -t O po 1- O M S r -C -t t- O 00 T 00 to z t~ -0 z ^ q "> to 1^ « W O m -r in C in n M M N r 0" N N WO in ** in ,, O O 3 r N rt O in O ro O- O. m O r~ in • in mr- 00 NO N M N i r-00 O N "t r* po in N PO O - CO >>, ■ ~ ■ M § 9 rt • ; > z Z 1 - QD ■ | u .J2 1 j 7 5 •0 <- 3 6 3 5 cE-o O rt c !>! fc ca 8 fa ^ M -■- £ -i ^ 3 8 a a I j: ■- •d go c c .2 Si is — 1 O - : 1 Z I 1 - E S ' 3 - ft. r- u. a 7, - CQ H 244 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR w f^H vO ►» i_ — C ""> «-i iO ° O ■ w « • • • • q_ ■* e ! oo" t? ; ; ; ; vo"vo" >> . 0 00 iO n-- Os Tf r^^O V """o ■* M V c tf CQ to i-i iO lONO O O N rj-o o >- •* • • "2 o«vo_ • • 1-1 'o so"; ■ >-*vo" cT io ■ >-H 00 lOsO «*5 ■* ■51- NtOM ^^ S?2 hvO M O "l^O '4-vO c II ►* SO 10«0 J^IO S_ ON m N f^fO Tt-00 O O O SJ 00 tn Cu^- u a J 9. °°. "? ""t "? "2 *"i ^ "t J3 8 fO ^f <> n" >O00" t^ ro C> 15 .*> Os "* fO r0 OssO i\OHiiot^.HiONO'*- H* 0"so" t^ w o" ■<£ oo" fC o" i-i CN CM rO^t^OOOO t->. hi N c || rOI^iO O ntOO O Os 1^00 lOsO C5sO O iCm [J **J mm N C5 1O00 O ION MMf| m oo en Ph «, o a X coco m on M i^moo W NfONO ro ^ so r^oo k^IOi-mOSMOOmhmhO i-n IO00 Os OO OO 00 00 00 00 00 00 00 EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 245 y c » © -r 5; ' in ' ', in I *+ «ooe O e « , " H Q\ -f- -t rO O CO ONO^ CJ • >o ■ ■ • • s 0" ' cTvo" 10 ! ►« .~ 10 t~- "^ "^ 1— . OS ' O t>» "*■ ' 00_ to ■<$ & ** SO en O ft s " Ov O M OO f5 N C> "^ fO - M _, HHHHdVi^ O a N m J O N «X -1" '1 C vo 00 O 00 r^ uo 1^ t^ 1^ 10 l>- IO Cl_ 0_ ~ Os "J "+• I-; M s rooo" r^vo k- c -t:' N ,~ O N « I s ! u"3 00 O r*» O O P*« m N Ji t^ M -t - CI SO f3 "3 vo*-M-*oot^Os>-'Osr^. O00O t^.00 i- CI t^— 1 - M M — r, ri t/1 c a W rt 2 00 O00 IOO "O «N*C O O t^OoO m -t-oc . O 1 ; s 0* co r^ cT cT 0* cT -«" OS CO SO t^fOW) 1^ uo t^ OsOO — co— OO 1 Os C — M to-t- u c "™ o" O tJ-cO"+cO'-«'-'»'5»0 1^ i-«ONOco"0OONt~- ■ * ' ^^ ""t °.°°. ~L *. °- 8 ' 10 ' w 1/^00" rf m r-^00" co i?» " «0 . COO "*■ 1^ cOO CI co 1—1 ct 00 <-> l^- »i-eo •* "+ 0_ rf coo" m" 10 N (O « tC u-,inM 00 >-> n M o" rh 00 ON O 8 10 : h ::;:::: : NO> C fO"t^-t« -+CIO0 O >o n HMMNflNdNni') O 3 > 1-1 0^ io •<*■ 1^ 1-1 000 n 10 8 nm"o t?0 N m i-T\o* w 10 «e 1000 iONOOO^HMW ?H N ** O O tOiO-tN« Nm_ 00~ t^ Ov i-<~ O^ t^ O O low l^ 00 m N Sm NNOO IONm MMMfiNNMNOIfO 5. i| l- ON 00 O N t-» •n-00 00 O On CO O t-» O^O HHMtt(?NMO« O N "^ COO CO CO M 00 C>N „^.n___N-iCOi-iOOhiO»0 UOCO In > co ■* "io t^oo a>o h n to OnOnOnOnOnOnOnO C C O OOOCOOCOCCCCOO On On O ON EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 247 =: X § — C -r ' - '- -1- N O00 C « O ic -t \r. oosnoo h HtOO p< 2 ~ ~ m m m c: z hoc 1 - m CO in - C X — -t C C -t". IH -tOO ~i-ci-~r-c_— -^~ tO - _t- _ <-, rr C - 1 - 0" £ -tOO 0" ir.ee -t c - in ~ o" n -t - <-i 1-1 1-1 n re t«3 to -1- m m to - t: — HMit *oc -t- ~ pi C C — ir. c. m £ X tO O C tC c ~ — - X C BC D_N to ~ -. "} -. N — js - t ^. -t \r. -f ~ O _"_"_"_' ~ tC fc 1 ~ X ir. 1 ^ - c- x r^rc C r^ _!: - " m -t r- c x ~- -t- -t -t — m to r «- pi : * - - fO CO O ©• X O C C~ — C m ro X ~ 1 - IC t*3 lOOO VO — ~ £ PI bH ". -t- ". N N -t -t C H -t -t t^ -, "- ir. -c NOC t^sC — r i — r^ K N vO \C ""• "". "~- — 9> -t ■£ - 0*£> OaO t^> 51 •" ir.NC ^C 'iXNtC" * LT; J tC fl "i" •+ mO IOWNMX1 -t 2 vC £ 1^ ts. N fC* "- 't N "5 N t^ E S I _ m ir; r— O mo wn h Tt t^ — e;x t^ ~ "". C *VO — _ w 3* mi in ures 1 (in issues — ir. O 1^- C~ -tO 't* to >-» »£ -f ~ x x x c x x - u-. c '1 r CN s~ _ -t- 1^ c n f^^o tn n "2 — r — m" pf co to -t — c r>.oe to 00* -t rt g U """ /. iC C* ir. c ^c >o w to W 1 - — -t- pi \r. r\ -t — [ ^ 1/-, c^ <0 PI 00 — C — C^l^— — Ti 10 >- '' — =£ b ~ ONod r 1 - - in - » - -tx" -f fc ~> r~\ 5 NO\M i-C— X"". ct- O Z -r-t-'iCiCCtOf". *t -t ^ - ~ "- -f -t n : ir. r c '1 m c -t »! \r. \r. ir. ir. t<3 \r. ~ rr -t 3 1 — if. 'i c; c ^ c 1 - -i" ~ C m — f. 1 ^ X 1 - 3" r > ""- 1 - ""• -*■ 1 - r^ - - - ^1 N M "". s a ~ > O H "■ — IT C 1 - X J ~ — ""I <0 -~rrrrrz : : : < r. r. /: r. x -C ~ r C C 248 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR ON T3 >- 1 » CO On - a K rn = O ft. ? M 1 X < On m cO — t^ C '1 O O ""- □ n0 ©\ N 1^ i~ o> r^ O X C C5 f0 3> - 0\ W M N fi X 1/". Z 01 "t5 t» 00" rf iC c£ M -f O* C? C* N Ifl 0" ;_ -f N i/l co mNO rf tc rf u-50 -too N O 00 h - r»; M ON m vO « O N -t'O — -t" CO ■+ 8 s — intoo>o*No»o 1^ <^j -t- \D OnX — CN in -f t--. C£X_X__ CO J3 S» 06" tONO On 00 -f *+• O -t- -1- I s * -f "*■ £ S,, rtO UO — CO — 1^ O O -t O N N n rf nO f^oo too N CN w CN O OM O mX IO -f -1" m £ O CO t^~ r^NO — ONtomX co X "£ -j £ 1^ ONX COX CN -f O X rf On r-» C U X fON + M "+ O lOONX r>- £ t^ rf X cOX O NM» cOX c "■r -f u ~ ^ CO N « N "_ * N 0_ C^ !> N 00 ty) c. hT CN~ CO CN CN~ rf CN CN CO vO* NO O On 10 I^nC X (O CO co -f rf r^ co r^ CN OnX cOnO r-» 0) — O c H. m rf rf >-i m rf CN in mO X c w On "") rf On O nO •-< On "0 >-> X £ in m co u X ~ « rS ^ -> ^ on o__ o__ rf w 10 10 rf q> *-f m M rf CO O* 00" 0" M On w — m N « N « m to O s, hemp, shi or nube rf cO O iOtOHvO»300 C rf O 0>NO N COX « O On CN CO N")NO On On O to t^ t^ co CO « of x" rT ^f on if) -f i-T m" co rC S On O NO NO «-" 10 J^nO N 11 1/) ON co ^ t^ CN X__ t--. 0__ O C_ "-_ rf t^ O; vq v O-a cftOCN CN cOCi rf rf rf IOVO N -c c rf s m\OSNO h m Ov-M N CO 11 uoioOnO 11 cn cn cot^O NO ^ rf ►« cn<_ 0_ rf rf t>. 0_ CO rf On W °3S s» r^ cono" 0" 0" t-^ t~^ t~~ t-^ o^x" £ NO "OnO co CO rt- M lOND in 01 in CO £ £h " r< 2 00 . oc l v£ i. o.^.^ .^. 00 . ^t >-<_ rt X* On t-^x" in CN* cn" rf rf o" rf in 2£ CN cOrfCN inrfvO rft>. t>. t>. ■/ : O > rorfino t^-X OnO — CJ - ^7 - 3 U x --■ = c » -t: "". '1 - r ^ — ^ f}—t r, r, ~ s_ O "". C r l X e a^oo 1- c«5 N 1 - - " 1/". N - i/-< r^ 1 - '1 I/ i/-, — C*3 X w 1 - - (N -r — u r*3 -1 "" s ~t t •>» » f^-C ~J~. 'i Z C 2 ;__ ir. ^m •+■ t^ D co l>. C M O* -t -f "", IT, 1C N - <~l roO *+ to i/i n — O N «-> Ifl^Nf; ■t: 1-1 CO N (N fC iO In - oo_ co 1- c> t-;0 t-~o_ « -r 10 *00 ^A pf o" O" -f <0 M O* d" to 00 i-c -1 i-x -r i^c ^ " n" «" co t-^ 1 - r 00 MO t^OO in P< ?r0f0 3^ ir; m -+x> 11 00 nO n C 1 ) •*■ H m co q_ N M_ q_ «T> CJ; O CO h m ^ n - r m" o" -f- 5 C C w> •**- C - M ^ o^o^o^o^o^o^o^i o c c oooooooooooo 00 cr r y 250 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR MOO vO t^O vO MOO OX OO^M>'/- rO OOOOvOOO i-i i-i -t t>. i^ oi_ ro Pl_ rt k 4fod vo oo" o t^ I s * eo -t od VO O — i i** 00 -t >o o PI «xx -t -t o U0 wco OCC OX moo m rOvO PI C\ -1-3*0 0 -1-^C iO -1- -+ -t to .r, <*> -a CO i — ■ OvO rO O vO 01 "0 01 lOtOn rO _c o to a* o o m n m -too ic >o O •<*; mh ro re m *t N 0_ 0_ 0_ Pl_ M Z p 8 ir>\0 c> "t t-» -t of ro t^ ro PI -t "3 u .*> lO O\00 00«mm[^PIMm PsO niot^ 'tOO CI O "J M 1"; o 3 a; xi X m O E ° rO ro "t ro -f r-^ r^'O io t-^^o q" Ui TJ « 03 > °£ \0 roX PI —> rO "t" i n O \C> _, O PI vO v£> X l/"3 rO O PI r<5N >o qv m« q_ IO a s uid rox" 1000" o" rf o -t c> ►H ■* vO "t en -v NCC m O h m ftlON ^ t^. c c NrOO ^-^O ro^O « 00 vO iO °J2 CJ CO lOiOiOO^rdO^O OtONM O ■s.a 8 m»o O00 NNOO « "tt U0 to ° k km 0_ CS N N ^ C; 0_ t-;0C_ "^ w -t 1-1 3 a) t^ ii ro lOOO -tt^N N t^oo O aT— VO -tiO-tiOO i/")cOO -trf IO bj0,O iO C_ « ©_.oo__ "2°o •* M^^ " Mt t3 •§. C o £ c£ m" o" cSvd" uo m" dc 4 d IO CO O .O NVO 'tOO J^ M Tt- (N M C^ PI ?H moo PI POP! r^OvOvO^O O rO o „ 3 X 8 8 co en CJ CO M ro "t Pi" ro fi o" of PO ^f rO Q K* 'C +j | r-" •s no o n o» omon o io "t o rt — - CTvON r^ m c3> l^vD on io\o (O U XJ tV SO 7 v3 uj -n ro\o" O c£ n of 0) o C^ o J" O^O^O 0|v£> O^NN PO00 rO MM 00 m\0 m N c^m N\£l nt<5 ro O rt vO (J CD ^3 spi sign CO oTpOPOuS-t-iO'tt^ r^\0 't o" IO u ^ vcoo oo O r^C\t^t^iO""api ro o VO C\ O rt^D O rO^C O "t -t IO u CMTvi^'tM/N moo 't'O c> °°. t) +j cu o > o . . C S o" tC ro iO d" ""i ^f CT^od" M i^ rO 'a 00 00 vO O ^O rooo N " N N vO +J mm . "OX O X vq _c PI i 'trorOPlO 01 lOro x~ — CO rO O.0I f)M>NO\0 Nt^iOO O n 01 X "tOO n ro "0 O rOrO PI u "t m « x rn "j pi r^x pi o lO rt S tf Mt d" ro Pi" C> "0 mT cS^o" u~> ro bo .^\D PI ro»OC « tC>NX O Ph ir> rox X OOvO^D lOrtO lO 3 lO C/3 « ro « ro C x" t^^" ro "t mT mmmiCINmN com n of 01 In "rt oj O H r^Tt-irivO r^X O O i PI ro OOOOOOOO O O C XXXXXXX OOOiCS EFFECTS ON COMMERCE 251 _ "3 r- s a s — rt - ;- u c — o T5 o C U - co r-~ 1/3 x 'i z z -r C — +■ ►* C c~ i^ — coc ~ ~ i^ r^ O POO OC 'i -T r i X t "} "t '~ s -' c* «- o" -t "f n >- r^ ^c o .- e -r z owe i-'ic i-cto .— -1- £ >C C X C C r t ft >■" CI rO IO00 O NNJO+B) « M C ~ r i C X C - - "- o X — Q Z ir.~/. I-~ I-". ^ ~ pi c c ""- -t- — r i m — ~ - •-_ t-^ to to -t z inco o o O C 00 CI >r. O — X - CO cO C i » — rO CN *C CO t^vO O "T CO O OwC -i- co C Z ci if. c_ =: Z 30 - *f - © nCCC r^ M .-rx--i-xc-i^— ~ JT 1 i—i -r £ -1- >f- x 3 to CO <•> — O ^ — CI ~C £ C ? fl •- C> N ■t ^ ci c, ic» . -1- -t- -t m ro -r io.vC r^oc c*> c - ci co Ov a o> o> o> o* o> c c o o 0C 00 00 00 00 00 00 0>t>0>0 252 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR O f) C*3 t^O On On 1^ l^- -1" OnO O i/". I^DO rO^fOX PI OnOO iO * __ -f io — O O MOMO O^M ? -f- C ir.oo" -f- m mjO |C\0 <0 c} ' 'l JO O Jifl -tO t-» O On On PI fOiOPI -tNflC -1- t^ CO o O r- On PI IO O r^NM On t^ PI IO IO ri -t -to c> pi C « O ^ n CO o_ , copper, d arti- 5 made ■refrom r-» t-^o ton pi t)-n'+« « 't oo inMfi t^o ioo»o pi n t^ "t 1 "t ^ ^ ^ '~; " 'i ^t 1 CO S vo 00 1^ cO t^~ « on onoo" o" w CO ,> vO t^00 O r-» OnO N 0>h ^) Pi com -t in N -t •+ N O00_ On "*■ r>. 2 rt ~- i/i^O' rfo" tJiOM* ON00 w CO mihmmmcCmhO 00 b/3— o" c .2 O 00 m O t^ PI iOO>OvtO^O CO O O r>. io pi « pi >o -t pi O ON NM CO Pl_ O_00_CO "2 O 'O 0_ IO "-5 sSS'-S § of cR w t-^oo" o" CO Pi" iO iO iO CO ^_ -t PI 00 O CO 1^. O O O i PI *t CO iO O IO PI On OnO "*■ CO ■n- ^T £.5 •* . — <- m n" pf pf co pi" pT co PI O iO 'tO t^ cO i I^O t^ CO IO CO OO wn»0>-iOcoOi o c ? o" t-^ -t »0 on « pT t-^oo" o" co 5 CO v rj- r^ IO 1^00 O PI I-* PI 00 On "*t On IO -*t00_ M 00.00 CO t~; ON ON C3 i co pT pT co »o r^oo" ^f io io r-C oo" IO On On IO PI ONCOf^t^PI Tt O Jv. IT;OlOO>0 MlflM O N N PI Im O O 00 PI iO 'too iO CO CO ■<*■ £ on t^vo -t^" ff o* (vf cooo" ^f 1 o oo" ^_ n ii o on io pi t^oo r— t^ pi " COO tO\"0 CO00 00 PI CO "* E °i « PI m CO PI CO O t-^ M PI — co COO IO CO ON PI ON O On o O 'too co io "i oo tj-o> m co PI ca a °. °_ "2 °t °i. °U '"t r 2 00 > "-l 00 . o i_ O^ <0 rl-OO -i iO OnOO PI Tf V o S ■ttON pf oo" On O" «"oo" O" O" 1^ . ^ 1/2 n lOO PI mi£I N N IOO ?i P|* ^O^ IO Pl_ ON 0.00^ I^ On o 2 o__ COX" 'f IO i »" IO CN h N m" OO" d Tf 11 W IC 00 — = c rt i q_ -l co i" pf pf pf pf *£ iO "rf rf IO o" CO c * _, O" NPI *hO 0>PI m O CO o c t^o onioi t^M-pivo r^»-i IO tj rt _. iT;NO CO PI CO t^O cONm ON o-c is t» I Pi fOO i-OM o rt-oo f^ y ni c3 te c u \. IOm N NPI -tM N 1000 i IO — O X ir,o tsN tJ-\0 t^ iO # c O ON'tPl COIOPI O>0 OnOn Tj- ~T, i «'N CO •* TtNO lOO t^-O as M >o cd > -o •* ioo r4oo' ftOMfi CO "e3 •l-l o H OnOnOnOnOnOnOnO O O O XXXXXXX OnOnOnOn EFFECTS OX COMMERCE 253 X ■0 _ c _ c" rt 2 a - a WX r~ c r~ c c c C 9 -1 1- T - O r- ". - — iy. LOfOoo iflOC nc x in Ck 00 00 di w e «"i c ?o/. 1- -too r- *• vmr^MMNT—C'iC; 1 f«3 r~ ^ — X r- Ct — O - C 1 1 ? © O (^ >-. r~0 r^O ©i r~x f* M r^3C m © O C t* W H "*} r^ inoo in m T *i — © CO ooc« « «o^ -00 c «f » <> "5 e ~:~: r-o©'©r~r~T©c tr. r~x ro0 One M 9 BC 1/: t "? "1 °.~® r I^ 0C . G. -. "' ? t c" inoo" t — n i^o~ -^ .T M ©> O O 0> « TO t- O O SNOlNromNTr-PlOTf^ « T TO © « O — O W t- O T O in q III E « rt ~> r- m X N O T C T ~ O©.r-Oroo©i©>r~r~© "J o_ 00 N T N 00 T in T r- S — O—o'TTr^ — r-c C , v O TO © O t~ ^ O 1 - C X £".TOOOXOCri'i- -1 "2 T O 00* u m 2 rt *n x nco •*» x *: x - N T ~ ^«» © © 1- r~ X x X O x H t M i , t^ l ;" i "* s: T *o O x t~ r- 'n T x* .^ 00 T m M — XX T TO S-iXOX©.»~oo-«fnOgo n j: n «- OOx — — (-ex s c^x' t -r *. t- r c us -» c *»lAOr^t^r*3MiAC>A — ~-. " °°. ". ^ *. N . ? t c . ~~- "'. _ MiAt~dLo">(noooT ? - « - - tirtnn^fln O 1^ r o> 0" X. CT> to n a E = u •rot E fl (0 O»«Xt~~;x--c C> O. O* *n m **> ~i £ «x r^io O in 0" COx"- T?C T~i«TX* ^"r^ot^S'O'CO TO O T *t" ". *?~ ". 'T*! c . T X inOOTO*— iflOOfin In ID c 13 H »o>oc»o>o>&ooop X X X X X X X O>&0>3> CHAPTER VI EFFECTS ON TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION At the outbreak of the war all the available transportation facilities in Japan, both land and water, were placed at the disposal of the government for the transport of troops and munitions from Japan to Korea and Manchuria, and, in consequence, the general public suffered considerable in- convenience. This state of affairs, however, did not last long, for the authorities concerned quickly adopted the necessary measures for relief; thus the transportation business was soon restored to its normal status, and never since has the general public suffered such inconvenience as at the outbreak of the war. Thus, except for this short period, transportation business in Japan was not hampered by the war at all, and all trans- portation facilities, both land and water, throughout the Empire, remained during the war in the condition as before the outbreak of the war. But after the war, which ended in Japan's victory, a great increase in activity was noted in the transportation, as in almost every other branch of business, as a result of the great postbellum boom in industry and trade. To meet this tendency toward expansion, many plans were formulated — by individuals as well as by the government. The latter planned for the improvement and extension of the railways and the telephone service, made efforts to augment foreign trade, and subsidized the merchant marine as well as the companies engaged in shipbuilding. The government raised the funds necessary for all these measures by public loans. How remarkable was the progress Japan made in trans- portation after the conclusion of the war in 1896 may be observed from the considerable increase in the paid-up capital 254 TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 255 of those companies engaged in the transportation business during the several years following the war. Compared with the year 1896, in which the war was concluded, the paid-up capital of the companies engaged in transportation increased by 100 per cent in 1900, and by 130 per cent in 1903, as will be seen in the table below : Capital Investment in Transportation Companies, 1896-1903 Authorized capital Paid-up capital No. of companies Year Amount Rate of increase Reserve 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Yen 171,674.964 266,973,250 271,896,976 269,622,304 305,810,809 356,220,426 361,454,333 383,422,606 Yen 113,216,760 164,684,165 197.233.421 198,146,560 228,733,512 243,224,584 262,676,192 262,382,936 100. 145-5 174.2 175 202 .0 214.8 232.0 231.7 Yen 6,259,011 6.551.967 7.302,391 ■s.i 133^4 14.s77.726 14,221,810 18,587,260 24,004.444 334 454 536 583 627 596 646 702 As the table indicates, the authorized capital of these companies increased by more than 100 million yen in the two years after the conclusion of the war, and then by another 100 million yen in the few years subsequent. Especially notewor- thy is this rate of increase, secured by the transportation companies during the several years following the war, when compared with that secured by companies engaged in agri- culture, industry and commerce. The extension of railways, those owned by the government as well as private roads, and the increase in the tonnage of merchantmen during these years were also remarkable, as the tables on the following page indicate. Of the systems of communication, which are under govern- ment control, the telephone service was extended at an outlay of 13 million yen. The condition of each of these branches of business will be presented in the following sections. 256 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Extension of Railways, i 893-1903 Year 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1 901 1902 1903 Mileage of railways Government Allies 558 58i 593 632 662 768 833 950 1,060 1,227 1.345 Private Miles 1,381 1,537 1,697 i,875 2,287 2,652 2,806 2,905 2,967 3,on 3,i5i Total Miles 1,939 2,118 2,290 2,507 2,949 3,420 3,639 3,855 4,027 4,238 4,496 Rate of extension Per cent 100. o 109.2 118. 1 129.3 152. 1 176.4 187.7 198.8 207.7 218.6 231.9 Increase in Shipping, 1893-1903 Year 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Tonnage of merchantmen Steamships Tons 104,909 163,029 207,765 227,840 268,223 287,857 308,402 330,622 357.394 376,n8 408,990 Sailing boats Tons 31,538 30,178 27,563 25,485 25,768 139,835 253,439 287,568 307,031 310,061 302,783 Total Tons 136,447 193,387 235,328 253,325 293,991 427,692 561,841 618,190 664,425 686,179 7ii,773 Rate of increase Per cent 100. o I4I-7 172.5 185-7 215-5 313-4 411. 8 453-1 486.9 502.9 5217 Transportation by Land The best way to discover what effect the war had upon systems of land transportation in Japan, as in the case of other branches of business, is to note the progress attained in the following years. The only means of land transportation in those days were wagons, rikisha and railways of various kinds. How the paid-up capital of companies engaged in land transportation increased in the several years subsequent TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 257 to 1896, the year in which the war was brought to an end, may be seen from the table below: Capital Investment in Land Transportation Companies, 1 896-1903 Year Steam railways Electric railways Railways employing hand cars Tramways Total Yen Yen Yen Yen Yen 1896 90,103,974 796,827 90,900,801 1897 130,663,015 44.640 130,707,655 1898 155,881,965 30,000 i55,9H,965 1899 156,967,016 42,400 157,009,416 1900 184,201,311 2,535,534 254,227 2,431.972 189,423,044 1901 196,539.372 5,419,225 307,391 1,059,409 203,325.397 1902 212,926,155 7.158,750 374.872 1,058,392 221,518,169 1903 205,319,921 13,089,005 451.504 1,364,544 220,224,974 No other means of land transportation was affected by the war as were the railways. Therefore it will be sufficient to inquire into the condition of the railways during these years. In 1893, or before the outbreak of the war, one-half of the Japanese railways was under government, and the other half under private management. The average working mileage of the government railways in those days was 558 miles and the average profit 16.91 yen per mile a day. The private railways were maintained by 15 different companies, and the average working mileage was 1,338 miles. 1 Profits from the railways under private management were 7.10 yen per mile a day; the rate of profit reckoned on the paid-up capital was about 7 per cent. Such was the state of Japanese railways before the war. In the next ten years, however, the working mileage of the government railways increased to 1,282 miles, or more than double the total mileage in 1893, and these railways brought in a profit of 21.82 yen per mile a day, or an increase of 30 per cent over that of 1893. Meanwhile the number of railway companies had increased to 41, and their total working mileage to 3,070 miles, or an increase of 1 The average mileage owned by each of these companies was 89.2 miles, and the paid-up capital 36,524 yen per mile. 18 258 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR 130 per cent; their daily profit also increased to 16.91 yen, or 1 >v about 140 per cent, compared with 1 893. This profit means 9 per cent on the paid-up capital of 67,845 yen per mile. Thus ihr Japanese railways made considerable progress both in mileage and profits in the ten years from 1893 to 1903. Let us now make fuller inquiries into the condition of the rail- ways, both government and private. In 1893, or before the outbreak of the war, the Japanese Government possessed 558 miles of railway, mostly what may 1 »e called trunk lines. This does not imply, however, that the Japanese Government neglected the construction of necessary railways in those days. On the contrary, the government promulgated the Railway Construction Law 1 on June 20, 1893, whereby a program was announced for the construction of railways in all parts of the country. This program, how- ever, was to be carried out gradually in different periods. In the first period, nine important lines were to be built at a cost of 60 million yen, to be secured by a public loan. But as soon as this program, or a portion of the greater program, was initiated, the war with China began, and the government naturally was compelled to suspend the work during the war. But Japan won the war, and after peace was restored, the Japanese Government in its postbellum program, prepared on a scale commensurate with the elevated position now occupied by the country, planned to improve the existing government railway lines and build new ones by floating public loans for this purpose. Thus the government agreed to procure a loan of 27,731,331 yen 2 , and of this total amount, to spend 26,553,000 yen for improvement of the existing rail- ways under the government, and 1,178,331 yen for construction of a line between Sorachita and Asahigawa in the Hokkaido. The government also agreed to build a trunk line on the same island by raising a loan of 33 million yen. 3 Then the govern- ment planned to build railway lines on the island of Formosa, 1 Law Xo. 4. 2 Public Works Loan Regulations, Law No. 59, promulgated March 29, 1896. 3 Hokkaido Railway Construction Law, Law No. 93, promulgated March 13, TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 259 ceded to Japan as a result of the war, at a cost of 28,800,000 yen, to be defrayed by a portion of the Formosa Public Works Loan. 1 Then, too, the scope of the original program, as announced before the war, was enlarged, and the appropria- tion for the first period increased from 60 million yen to 95 million yen by Law No. 19, promulgated on April 2, 1901. The new lines thus planned and the cost of their construction were as follows: Construction and Improvement of Government Railways, 1893-1903 2 Construction of railway lines, 1 893-1903, built with pro- ceeds of government railway loans: Yen Yen Fukushima-Aomori line 2 °i773i993 Hachiwoji-Nagoya line 20,300,532 Shinonoi-Shiqojiri line 6,410,865 Yatsushiro-Kagoshima line 6,050,676 Tsuruga-Toyama line 9,407,302 Himeji-Sakai line 5.574-331 Kaidaichi-Kure line 2,152,600 Fukuchiyama-Sonobe-Maizuru line 1,341,459 Expenses for superintendence 200,019 72,211,777 Improvement of existing railways under government management, 1896-1903, from proceeds of Government Public Works Loan: Tokaido line 21,0 (7,422 Shinyetsu line 1 ,039,545 Street railway line in Tokyo : 2,763,340 Yokohama harbor line 28,41 ' J Kobe harbor line 7° 1 • 7' \S 25,720,476 Construction of railway line between Asahigawa and Sorachita, Island of Hokkaido 1,176,701 Construction of new lines, 1 896-1903, from proceeds of Hokkaido Railway Loan 5,889,305 Construction of new lines, 1899-1903, from proceeds of Formosan Railway Construction and Improvement Appropriation 14,894,227 Total 1 19,892,486 By these means the total mileage of the government railway lines was increased considerably, as the table given below indicates. The increase is indeed remarkable compared with the total mileage of 558 miles in 1893. The following table gives the annual increase, for the years 1893-190,}.' 'Formosa Public Works Loan Law, Law No. 75, promulgated March 20, 1899. 2 Fractions over 5>> sen Air counted .1- whole yen; fractions under ~ disregards I. 3 Railways built in Formosa dining these years not included. 260 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Miles Chains 1893 1894 23 20 1895 12 40 1896 38 40 1897 30 03 1898 90 19 1899 40 29 1900 72 79 1901 81 74 1902 131 °7 1903 93 42 Total 613 53 All this extension of the government railways was a part of the program which the Japanese Government, stimulated by the war, had prepared to harmonize with the elevated position assumed by the nation after the Sino- Japanese War. Not only was this a direct effect of the war, but there was another cause for this extension of the railways in Japan, namely, the vast increase in the number of passengers and amount of goods carried by train, due to the increased activity in the ecomonic world in Japan after the war. This increase in both passengers and goods naturally brought about a corresponding increase in the profit from the railways. This cause may therefore be called an indirect effect of the war. The number of passengers and volume of goods carried, fare, gross returns, business expense, etc., of the state railways are given in Table I at the end of this chapter. 1 The gross income, profit, etc., of these government railways also increased in these years, as indicated in Table II at the end of this chapter. 2 The progress of the government railways during these years was remarkable in every respect. Let us now look at the extension of private railways which, like the extension of the government railways, was carried out on a scale commensurate with the increase in economic activ- ities after the war. This extension in the railways under private management was also remarkable, as the increase in the number of companies, their capital, working mileage, etc., given in the following table indicates. 1 Post, p. 265. 2 Post, p. 266. TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION Extension of Private Railways, 1893- 1903 26l Year No. of com- panies Authorized capital Paid-up capital Reserve fund Loans Average working mileage 1893.- • 1894.. . 1895- •■ 1896.. . 1897.-. 1898.. . 1899.. 1900.. . 1901.. . 1902.. . 1903- • • 15 20 24 26 32 42 43 41 40 41 41 Yen 63,145,000 80,290,200 99,228,000 120,015,000 175,396,000 213,886,150 227,799,300 238,042,550 242,585,000 251,675,000 256, 575.°°° Yen 48,869,515 59,176,637 71,626,301 89,010,597 122,542,091 153,924.70;, i69.9W.444 181,267,472 192,811,305 202,603,626 208,285,567 Yen 517,975 1,322,085 1,161,682 1,587.045 2,169,267 2,681,711 3,374,353 3.635.854 4,401,343 5.155.920 6,038,419 Yen 5,680,000 5,778,000 5,552,000 5,350,000 5,410,000 10,174.365 10,640,400 11,017,800 12,839,000 12,852,600 18,364,400 1,338 1.457 1,617 1,698 2,027 2,466 2,725 2,841 2,944 2.978 3.070 The business of these railway companies was stimulated by the general activity in industry and commerce which followed the war and their capital greatly increased, as Table II indi- cates. Let us now note the increase in number of passengers, volume of goods, etc., as given in Table III at the end of this chapter. 1 The increase in the number of passengers and volume of goods carried by these railways naturally brought about a corresponding increase in the receipts, as shown in Table IV at the end of this chapter. 2 The railways in Formosa, which were entirely built by the Japanese after their acquisition of the island, as a result of this war, made a very good showing from the beginning, for in a few years after construction these railways brought in some profit, as Table V at the end of this chapter 3 shows. In conclusion it may be stated that the war did not have any direct effects upon or give any marked stimulus to railway business in Japan; yet it is true that the railways achieved considerable progress in the several years following the war, because of the general awakening of the nation and improvement in the country's position brought about by the war. This progress made by the railways may therefore be said to be, to no small extent, the result of the war. l Post, p. 267. *Post, p. 268. l Pcst, p. y 9 262 economic effects of the sino-japanese war Transportation by Water Merchant marine In this section we shall give an account of the progress attained by the various organizations constituting the mer- chant marine of Japan, during these postbellum years. At the outbreak of the war, many merchantmen were transferred to the government service for the transport of troops and munitions, and the merchant marine as a whole was somewhat hampered in consequence. Especially was this the case with coastwise navigation. But this temporary inconvenience was soon remedied, for the government quickly chartered foreign vessels and put them in the places of the replevined. merchant- men. For the remainder of the time, therefore, the Japanese merchant marine did not sustain any serious injury from the war, but remained in its normal condition. After the war, the government, stimulated by victory, adopted all possible measures to secure progress in the merchant marine, as in the transportation systems on land. Help in the form of govern- ment subsidies was given for the construction of good harbors, for instance, at Nagasaki and Osaka, so that these places might be converted into good trading ports. The construc- tion of new vessels and overseas navigation were also en- couraged by the aid of government subsidies. For the former the government promulgated the Law to Encourage Ship- building l on March 24, 1896, and for the latter the Law to Encourage Overseas Navigation 2 under the same date. The companies which enjoyed state bounty in accordance with the former law were only such as were composed of Japanese subjects, either wholly or in part, engaged in the building of vessels, and owning docks equipped as specified by the Minister of State for Communications. 3 An encouragement 1 Law No. 16. 2 Law No. 15. s The rate of subsidy given in accordance with this law was \2 yen per ton of gross tonnage for steamers whose gross tonnage was between 700 and 1,000 tons; and 20 yen per ton of gross tonnage for those whose gross tonnage was 1 ,000 tons or over. In case an engine also was built, an additional subsidy of 5 yen per horse power was given for the engine. TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 263 bounty for overseas navigation was given those individuals or companies composed either wholly or in part of Japanese subjects that with their own steamers, registered by the Jap- anese government, were engaged in the transport of goods or passengers from a Japanese port to a foreign port, or from one foreign port to another. 1 A steamer eligible to government subsidy was to be made of either iron or steel materials, to be the best grade of steamer, and possess all the necessary quali- fications specified by the Minister of State for Communica- tions. In addition any steamer eligible for the shipbuilding encouragement bounty was to be of more than 700 tons gross tonnage. And any steamer eligible for the overseas naviga- tion subsidy was to be more than 1,000 tons gross tonnage, and have more than 10 nautical miles maximum rate of speed. Besides these two forms of government subsidy for merchant marine, another system was devised for those steamers engaged in navigation service to ports in America, Europe and other foreign countries. This last form of subsidy was inaugurated because the Japanese Government, desiring to encourage the shipbuilding industry at home, was anxious to encourage overseas navigation. Through encouragement from the government and the stimulus of the increased activity in commerce and industry during these post-bellum years, the Japanese merchant marine made remarkable progress in the several years follow- ing the war, as Table VI at the end of this chapter- indicates: The number of steamers, registered tonnage, number of passengers, volume of goods carried, paid-up capital, etc., of the three principal steamship companies in Japan, namely, the 1 In the case of a steamer whose gross tonnage was 1,000 tons, and whose maxi- mum rate of speed was io nautical miles per hour, the rate was 25 sen i>er ton of gross tonnage for each 1,000 nautical miles of the voyage. This rate of subsi.lv was increased 10 per cent for every 500 tons increase in the gross tonnage, and 20 per cent for every nautical mile of increase in the maximum rate of speed per hour. For steamers whose gross tonnage was more than 6,500 tons, or whose maximum rate of speed was more than 18 nautical miles per hour, the same subsidy was given as for a steamer whose gross tonnage was 6,0( tons, or maximum rate of speed 17 nautical miles per hour. More or less discrimination was made accord- ing to the age or whether the steamer concerned was built in Japan or abroad. 2 Post, p. 270. 264 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Nippon Yusen Kaisha, the Osaka Shosen Kaisha, and the Toyo Kisen Kaisha for the years 1 893-1 903 are given in Table VII at the end of this chapter. 1 Communication The war did not have any direct effect on the systems of communication in Japan, but after the war the government by an appropriation of 12,802,107 yen established new telephone systems in Kyoto and fourteen other large cities, and at the same time connected all these important points by telephone with Tokyo and Osaka, the two largest cities in the Empire. The first telephone in Japan was established between Tokyo and Yokohama in 1890. Then another line was run between Osaka and Kobe two years later. The fifteen cities where the government established telephones as a part of its post- bellum program, at a cost of 12,802,107 yen, in the years sub- sequent to 1896, were Kyoto, Nagasaki, Niigata, Nagoya, Sendai, Kanazawa, Hiroshima, Akamagaseki (Shimonoseki) Fukuoka, Moji, Kumamoto, Sapporo, Hakodate, Otaru and Utsunomiya. The appropriation referred to was apportioned as follows: Year Annual appropriation Year Annual appropriation 1896 Yen 594.196 2,473,420 1,896,119 1.781,655 1 900 Yen 2,349,786 1897 . . 1901 1902 1,807,587 1898 1,615,532 1899 1903 268,556 Further than this there is nothing of importance to state about the systems of communication in Japan in these post- bellum years. 1 Post, pp. 271, 272. TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 265 rj- moo 11 r^. m o* « cm **- w •&<« •tO N N NO^PI 3>" +^ of) u 00 ~ CM COOO CI t^- CM n \0 fO 'S s m N N N (H HM't-in "50 u. 01 So .2 s 2 + 1/JN tooo CM >o CM r>» to IOOO n O 1^00 NOONWN nO nO t^OO 00 s O O 1 W ■ -t C/5 ^-* "o a 0. d £ aa 01 r* "*J CM t^ ►* tOOO r-» fO r-» t^ to to O -t"NO t^OO IO 11 -3-00 O IO — E h 11 n n ci to to to •+ •"?/■ ""5 J — O O~+NO0\O fOCMJ N insa>o n m ci no r^oo , , 00 IT>00__ Cf; >o rf o_ C^vO O; t>; c3 8 -*f 00" "*• 0" 00" CM~ to O" to to m " O V> rr> 1 vO fONO to CI ^t-iONO >i O 00 "<*-vO *n o_ O; o_ «r> to lOiONNcSo'fO'f i/*)nO 00 ioo^^n coo r^ on -i-ao E •S.S- 8 CO O^OO'vO" -f O 1 ^ 4 COCO •n qj .*> rf-00 O "+nO 1 fOO^O 100 >< cm_ "200 O C_oo__ n "t t °. ^ c s « u. ^ M m* m" w N «" to "t 4 w in M IOO M "HOO » « f l "J a) O O 1 00 0> N "0 t^NO CM 1 10 "t^^t . ".'^t^ C <3J S m" ^\o" >f to IN 1 ~ 00* O CM ^ h .« OMN IOOO O CM On •<*■ "*• CM On Ph r^ cm no c^o 1^ cm -ho »o m t/5 C3 n to>tiniONMjo c — r i Cu O*O0 On On -*-nO h O (1 O N EO 00 On "0 1 IO- C> t^NO O M CM V E ■g ^OtNOi-OO-t IOO t^vO S nO 00 0" vcT 00" to 1 vd d to CM - L_ I^.n O NO 10 J>0>0 moo On " O O >• N ION fOOO NO — •+ 3 -- "o t^vo t- t<« -t- fi O -f IOnO 3 cm 00 00 -t- i^no 00 >o m -1-00 la ocm 00 -1-1- a r rtOO 1^ 1^ O ICC O C X) O 5 9 a a **• ^00 N NmX » M » -t < m ~ m m n rOM tOtOtOtO rt B to "-)- "OnO t^OO On O ~ CM to OnOnOnOnOnOnOnO 00000000000000 O^OnOnOn 266 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR -c c „_ B-S S* e s 5 bo CO | o a £<* en 2a o u Ph ►i to •*00 O "- 1 o vo o "■> CM ^ vO StOOvOOO cOvO CM CM « "mmMmNmNNNNM 0) (/> U3 3 C jo oj .2 g a o j» ir> uo t^oo nm^hOOh •^ CT\ O h ►*• MMMNNNNNtlN en -m o £ vO O OnN lOiOO^ cOvO CM VO g *N N "Oh PI N t>0 "tO> ^ VO 00 t^vO i-i CM vO 00 IO + N CM CM rorO^-^^*-'i u ^-^-^- Average working mileage 5 oo >ovo moo* r^vo o i- cm ■-^ lOvO 00 M *N h ^N fOOO £ 1/5 lO lOvO VD 1^.00 00 O h N F^ >-t 1— 1 »H ■u o Ih Ph O r^ cm ©\ "i oo rn o toN* OO i-i t^OO rf rOvO h Oh m O r^vO on 'd- O^ cm cm cm ■* cm 8 cm" tC CM~ tC hT rf oo" ^oio N .*> Tj- CO ""5 >0 -^-00 ONN Nh >1 t^vO O Tj-O^t^O t^CM CM_CM_^ CO CO "5 rF •"£ tf t^oo'oo" ON o" — — • 3 C .a e Q lOvO h tOO\ M N U"5vO »0 >h r^ awo ^o ^iohvo n\o o CONO u"ivO O 0> >h iO CM_ i-<_ CT; S cm" ih" hT io\o" o*\o" >h t-Cvo"\o K ^ ^j-00 iOhOOOO O t^ •^-vO On >i On ih onoo t^ CO t-» CM lO O 00 IH CM CM CO rj-v© NO f^OO On On to t/> *J iO CO CO CM O On T> lO O" CM iO iom com onoo nnmoo m ■* Tf CM VO "d-00 tO N lO lO h 8 rfc^'^fcOt^iO^f'OvOvO 0> ,*> oo w o r^cMvo o i-Ntoo hi COOO OWN "I 00 . 0_ I s ; ^0 "-^ lO looooo" Q\ i- CONO VO CO o M M M M M N cs rO •* lOvD r^-oo O^ O <-■ CM CO OMj>OOt>00^0 o o o 00000000000000 0\0>ONON TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 267 4J ir, m^3 m m nnvOCO 1— ©\ •? <« \o "",00 •+ m -» "1 "^00 CO O NOO "t *g 2 c<3 *t 10 \0 00 O M Tf Tf lOvO [X, MWM M CO So .2 u 'u ID 00 rT to \D 00 00 U)C>NC'H t~» t^OO O vO i^NN to M too to m 03 to N "tOoo m cjTt msO v»- M 1-1 M M «3(0(T0<^ O O ^ to CD > M i<)m CJ\vO iO m N tO'tM m MCN tOOO l>» O Tf t>- <0 O N N tO Tf VO «^00 00 O O O £ _~ q — < M O tO 1-1 C>« lONf5^"2 00 to tOvO o o^^o >o M , Tfl^OOOOO 11 1-1 vO O O M_ rt e m 0" m" m c? c? m n 0" 0" 10 M 00 lOtS M M O IOCS pH ION N^O C> Tf fi O tOP) CC O H iOIsIJm lOCTvtor^OO O O mmmMNNNCO vO vo t^^o r-» r*» 0^0 mom lO(H NVO -+00 t^» too vO 0) +_j to "So. ioi^m toio r~»oo to O >o c 8 ^D fOOo" C> >0 c£ Tf v£5 1- M M "8*8 .*> vO to to fO IO O O M to lO^O " M c t: 00 . ^t °- ^t °i °i *t " °- c £s? m~ m" to -rf \D r-^00 ■- r^ m~ QJ U .OON03+ONNON CvO ^i -f tOOO M O^OMi ■- 0000 to rt rt^ to Tf "5 1^» O »i Tf vc r^» t^» Ch Tf Tf to M >00 too O I- O 6^ OvO ")h m fOO VO >0 »0 C7^ tO-t"tO>-i to M iO^h OvO -. -t-LOi-i OO MOO Tf O 00 00 3 5 11 \0 rO N N N M C^ lO tO^O "3 bo O £j Tf M M IO O i-« * IT) N 0> N M tO Tf »0 1^.00 O i-i i- 1 M Tf iOhmO Q lOJi') "tO 00 i IOIOO w- 0) 00 to •- tovO >-• M 0_ cr -r 1 ; co O" c£ ■- 00" IO «i M* \0 O — — . c 0- rO IO N 1^ t>» TlvO to M v£> OvO »1--t-— "1- tM^ •"■ i-ioo O 4) ., to rt a 00 i-i O rO N I- t<) m COO C^ h n n>t io\o t^oo 1^ t^ t~» u m ::::::::::: fO Tf lOvO t^.00 OO h N (O ooooocoo 00000000000000 0000 268 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO- JAPANESE WAR > o Q. -a c «>N en CM *j -o c m 01 CO £ Om o g m OnOO rJ-fN 0>(Oh O 0»0 j£| I/O "OnO CXJOtNeNrO-rl-Tl--^- en .9* "53 o cu u en en O In r *i ior^»«>-«»«>-<00O uooo O ^ (N rl-r-^ On CN fO^NOO i-i "MMMMNNN«f|tOI<) o OO C>0 O^O 00«N O O O ^1-nO •*i-' te<5M no n .V \C •j-^O CO (N r<0NO O 'd- Tf O >i ^£nO_ E o> en u 3 XI en 5 CJ\ On lOO t~- "d" O NO NO rO >-i Tf I/O t^ (N •**- >-i t}- lOOO tN O ". ■"£ ^ 't °. "2 "2 "I. °. ^1.^ S cnT I/O iO rCod 00 O co r^ O lOO « rj-rj-t^ >** OnOO CO COOO 1/5 iO O NO CO ^J- lO N O tNNO' O rf O^ >- fO lO h m - n N tl e<)e<5to u s ro "d- "oo r^.oo a>o m « to 0n0nCJnOCn3nJ>0 O O O OO 30 00 00 00 00 00 O^OnOnO TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 269 r> a a a r vo ifln moo - > O00\O ON V c rt X S" "-T !*• -f vOvO £3 H PQ ' ^~- .J. 5 t^\o 00 * s "° .. c £ W So >o 00 t^. o> n! S O lOOO f5 O CivO ^ 5 00" in cT vo o nT O h J~ -< o> C. <-> " mo co\o 1000 m uh a « - - - (S ■. t^. C}vO >*■ (N ° en rj- 10 i •- 0, t^NO_ t>. >-<_ O M ro 11 8 10 O" \6" O" C> "f >0 r° OnO ►"> On ro ►« O > en iC« r^ tJ- O bO rj-vo nO 00 r^-\0 «+• M M IO O_O0_ Tf O . C IO00" rO ro r^oo On O •» -a r-» r^.oo >o i ci i o "5 o to h °o ^too ci ci & o> -+ o ci t^t^ £ « * (^ to fO OO 00 >-i *t n t^ in c O (O "~/ f^ ^ ^- M 00 -to i "5b S tO 0> tO IO O^ « O n O 00 t— ,— M ri n r-\ -(- ioO O O J~— u O too -to — 00 CI O ONO0 H t/J Ofl no cs to to to to to o^ h O S rt CO -t-O CO O O lOO moo to 2 s o 01 rt O O t-» tooo O 01 01 t^» H og O OO CnIOhh^d -tO tON 01 0) to CO "t\D t^ao Cn O 0\ 00 O w "0 t~» "+0 CO -t -t 01 „Q mIOO to 0\CO too tON o g oo t^t^t^a^"^- 1 >oo o__ 3 m" to 4 "t 4 4 £ TD 4) CJ COCO to co ir; bo CO t^-O CO O to cOO COO 00 2 rt «0 i iO rt t^.00 "t "^ 0_ 0_ N .22 c "5c 5 M"o"N1010C?>tONNO N tOtOM n M to IO00 O n O v 2 m N M COtOtO Ph~ tn 1 tn bfl O O 01 « nCOO OONC-O £ «« lO« COn "ttOH CO 0~> « "5 M 2 g CON C^NNC^OO 'too O C tOtON N N -tNO N N PI s n 01 tO to co CO a) COO tOiOn O toOMOM rt JD m CT> I^O N"X O O On n 6 3 pj _ — _, _i co t^. co iO »0 "0 n r>| CO CO CO CO £ T3 0) m o oo 'tNinONOM a £2 rt C£ 0I_ t-;00_ Cl_00_ -tO CO «_ ON « S ■ttON rCoo" rCoo~ o* t-^o'oo OO O 01 O 00 O cO"0r^-O m h p| P| N p| totototo* in & u a> "■*■ O "*■ co "^-O O 0>iOMO (U to bo oo t^ cn pi •tNtoc>N "t- e en as O c O o PI tOtONvC (S tOPI miO N « C> of <-* to 0> 'too" tf r-^ ^fvo" 01 O O COO CI O Cn co t^ O iO en i pi cotO't^t'tiO >0O O 0) o ooo oo ttoa>o> tooo JD OO fl NPI MO lOO CO00 S rf-tiOiOOO t^oo C> O O 3 1 *1 £ u 0) to ■* u->0 t^OO CJ\ O i ci co Q\OCTvQvOOOO O O O 00000000COCOCO O*0»0>0i TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATION 271 y. H es c/3 -O O O bo "o = 3 > fed bd b-H c O O N IONM ^.C^O «*3 £ ------ y S rOrOiOt^CTOOCO 11 O — to tn u bfl c tn in C/} O n o> M^ C> H — — 00 rC^ -<_ 'to oo_ v >' £ ,M O NN 1^00 rot^OO "~. » O *ni-- ~ m t c to t*» 0) bO 03 B B O -a u U V m "53b a* ^ w H (^ ■<+■ -t ro CN1 N {«, rtO ON "iifl ■/'. O '-"• -t C 00 tOtOIH —00 "+ rC -t x 00 *t- £ o> 1000 «-n.o -toe — -t >00 O ^O (H -tO 00 ft lOlO f2 00" n" 0" ro — ' 0* vo" -> O 00 0\ — t/3 Q O O lOO CJ — rOCf^'Tl'-'OO • •^1010 lOO O "0 1000 00 ^ Oi V. a > rO -t lOO t^OO O O — f 1 <-0 0\0>OiO>0<0>00 00000000000000 9 T ^ T- 272 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR tt e U! H •o c 01 -v M jj 1/5 i/J UOO NOOvO POt^OO O O O O 6 rt « W 8 io UOOO O *h»00 O NMM H fc. - - N « m W IH IM Z 1? t^ r-~ t^- cjvO oo O^O W . . -^-""OrDi-idN-t - g . . . io •- oo r^vo m_ ^t^o. W - 1 i2 fcd jj t — i— ■ io>- O ^C^Cf; 1 -^ O_00_ us c/5 o d i-c C5^0 01 Tj" lO ON lO 1/5^0 MOO MO 'd-O <~0 N <*5*0 ►-" 00 O N rf-00 O I s - 01 vO t^ o W t^-r^M O O u 2 T t^t ,- l 't^ § pf co oo" o in o" t-^ "5 •* c m >< ii. "3-00 -ii-i N M TflO^-* ooi-^ooooo O'+iOOOOOO w • • • o_ "*; m_ o_ o_ o_ o_ o_ § ! '. '. «nvo rC o" O o O o HH H "rt ►h M CI c*5 **5 <*5 ro t*5 OOOOvOOOOOOO 'a coooooooooo W s q_ o_ o_ o_^o_ o_ o_ o_ q_ o_ o_ u i^ o" o" 0*vo" oo" o" o" o" o o" o o "* Tt- o^o o o o o o o a 3 t/5 d 00 o-o^o o 1/51/51/51/51/510 M " m* m" N* lO U5 U5 lO lO U5 U5 12 Oh 00000000000 00000000000 ui ocoooooooq_o_ « 0" 0" 0" 0" ■<£ 0" 0" 0" 0" 0" 0" >« <» 00000000000 rtOOOOOOOOvO OOOOOO £ 00 00 00*00 O N N (1 N M 1-1 N CS CS M M M In 0) >* r0-*"5>O r^oo O O w M f*5 00000000 00000000000000 OOOO o o H a < < w v. W CA. D :* V. o CHAPTER VII EFFECTS ON PRIMITIVE INDUSTRY It may possibly be correct to say that the Sino- Japanese War had little direct effect upon primitive industry in Japan, although indirect effects were noticeable here and there. For instance, the interruption in the transportation of general merchandise, both by land and water, due to the transporting of troops and munitions at the outbreak of the war, caused a lack of balance between supply and demand for the products of various branches of primitive industry in the Empire. In consequence the prices of such commodities as lead and other contraband, coal, provisions, dried bonito, salted greens, pickled plums, barley, soy beans and certain munitions, rose somewhat. It can not be denied that the rise in the prices of these third- class commodities in particular gave their producers — farm- ers, mine owners and fishermen — an opportunity to enlarge the scope of their productive capacity and so to increase prof- its. The rise in the prices of these commodities may there- fore be regarded as an indirect effect of the war upon primitive industry in Japan, but even this was not so great as to be worth special mention. But the measures that the Japanese Government adopted as a part of its post-bellum program for the development of various branches of primitive industry are worth special notice, although they, too, may be called an indirect effect of the war. These measures included the establishment of an iron foundry under state management 1 ; improvement in the condition of rivers to secure better irrigation; the establish- ment of more agricultural experiment stations and sericulture] training institutes, the enlargement of those already in exist- ence, etc. Furthermore, the government established such 1 Full particulars arc given in Chapter II. 19 273 274 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE S1N( )-JAPANESE WAR banking systems as the Japan Hypothec Bank of Tokyo, and the hanks of agriculture and industry located in various parts of the country. All these banks engaged in the business of lending money on security furnished by real estate. These banks were started to give increased financial facilities to farmers, who were suffering from the lack of funds for their work. Of course these banks were imperfectly adapted to their purpose of developing the agricultural industry in Japan; especially in the case of farmers with small capital did they prove defective. Nevertheless it can not be denied that these banks gave an impetus to the agricultural industry and practical assistance to farmers. This may be proved from the fact that the greater part of the money that the Japan Hypothec Bank and the banks of agriculture and industry advanced in various parts of the country, through the system of redemption by annual instalments, was lent to the irriga- tion and earth-work guilds, all composed of farmers, as the figures in Table I at the end of this chapter 1 indicate. There is no denying the fact that they really did benefit many farmers who had been suffering from lack of capital to carry on their business. Advances by Banks of Agriculture and Industry, 1898-1903 Year a To agri- culturists To agri- cultural companies For adjust- ment of arable land Total Grand total 1898 1899 1900. . . . 1901 .... 1902. . . . 1903. . . . Yen 2,297,870 7,163,043 11,095,842 13,342,196 14,931,925 17,1114,710 Yen 18,001 25,126 34,595 58,852 Yen 5,270 4,869 4,431 60,241 Yen 2,297,870 7,163,043 11,119,113 13,372,191 i4,97o,95i 17,313,803 Yen 3,687,490 10,522,750 16,647,648 19,994,537 21,701,288 24,296,668 Close of year. Areas under cultivation in rice and wheat since 1893, showing the improvement effected by the aid of the above- mentioned banks, are tabulated on the next page. 1 Post, p. 276. EFFECTS ON PRIMITIVE INDUSTRY 275 Areas under Cultivation in Rice and Wheat, [893-1903 Rice Wheat Year Area under cultivation Price (per koku) Area under cultivation Price (per koku) 1893 Cho 2,769,478.9 2,736,494 -6 2,784,682.5 2,792,499.4 2,787.181.3 2,817,624.0 2,839,550-2 2,828,459.9 2,847,357 3 2,847,191 .9 2,864,139.1 Yen 7.08 8.24 8.21 9. 16 II. 81 13 11 9.84 II.32 11.47 12 .07 13.68 Cho 1,744,010.3 C753.409 -8 1,774,159.8 1,767,043.2 1. 74'). 571- 7 1,806,667.4 1,809,822.6 1,806,668.6 1,816,200.8 1,804,938.0 1,799.346.1 Yen 3 T* 1894 1895 3 3 3 4 6 4 4 4 4 6 75 80 1896 1897 1898 57 88 04 46 74 07 45 [8 1 899 1900 1901 1902 1903 The areas under cultivation in rice and wheat as given in the foregoing table refer to the lands on which rice or wheat was actually raised, and not to the entire area prepared for cultivation. Besides, the area of cultivated land changes according to the conditions of crops each year or the price of rice or wheat; therefore these figures can not be accepted as exactly reflecting what these banks did for the agricultural industry. Vet to some extent we may see by these figures the progress made by their aid. In addition, the governmenl established a training school to develop fishery experts, and adopted various other meas- ures to improve the fishing and mining industries. As these, however, are not worth special notice, we shall content our- selves with a glance a1 statistics regarding the paid-up capital of the companies engaged in the agricultural industry during these years, as shown in Table II following. 276 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR N *N hOO N •(• f fO-tc^'^O O c O t^-00 ^ IOhCO_ 3 S vO \0 ■* "t fi 0" « .<" t^ O t^. 1^-vO -too >i mi-» f» *noo CM vO_ "73 <" S £ ° < ►h vO ao" 1-1 WNm O c M M W CU c-o CD 00 tf "+ "t" ON N 00 rt 03 £1 p, ^O -t- >o O 1- O s 3 2 m N CO") "^t 00 . M Pj" N M lOI/JCH " h 4-> m O tOcOM + H c ^ -t N N IO " 1^1 N 3 O 6 S c> 1000" 1-1 1000 (^ C?C5 *rt 11 00 lO CN 10 rf -+ a M fl C3 0\0_ 3 pf £ CO lO cooo O On "* 3 O -tNONM in d .2 m NO>O^N On NO 00 O O j3 H s IOhvO co CN CO •"*• lO^O r-» 3 fc c 3 O s < O NM OW M "c3 <* ■ O On OOO O CM ^ • On CO^O CN_ t^vO *-> .„ 5 8 h^ rf -t co co 1-1 00 "3 S O 2 CO co co CO t^vO •g a bC S u nj O ° 0) 3 • CN CM P* CM xO NO H £ OMOIOtOO^O 10 C 3 O u")\0 TJ-MO0O0 CO g t^ CO CO O On i-4_ CM •r? O k!° pf m T-f rf w r-Cvo" >l TfCM> 'tOO PI NO 3 s < CO CO CM Tj- ■* CM Tt 3 1-1 CM CO *tNO 00 # o °u In be CU i-h CO COOO O t^ ^t aj £> *-> \0 1-1 i^» r^^o O E i-h 1-4 cooo on H 3 ■ u « a > f^OO O 1-4 CM CO OOOO O O O 00 00 00 ON On On O EFFECTS ON PRIMITIVE INDUSTRY 277 CT> rO c- r>» -too — ro O ro r^ 00 10- O -tvo r^ — r^ -1- — "t "c5 IJHMN O "5 IO rf ci" — " — h - - '1 n C> -t O r- lOOO MOO O O IO O vOOOO Tf t^OO NO N O -- r l 00 tQ jj ro q_ <*i NO NO CI C 00 IflNf 00 on ,»>0 ci 00" IO CO -too" r^M* COCO 0" rNvO Cl> CI COO IO (S CO CO 00 On 00 M o" CI -1 1-1 01 IO w — rO O >Om OiOdOt^r^Ol^ ■" ro if Pi rOOO O CO00 -f r-C ci ro ~ 0" hT CI CI -tO CO IO00 CI 10 *N N CI « m M (<5(S M 10 ci -t O C" Cl O 1-^00 OlOON NO O 10+ O 01 O N ro rOO 00 1^ — ~ — t^ fN M -t C 0I_ -+■ 0_ 0_ IN I-; ,8 ,f vO M •-T «-T c^ 10 0" 0" o IO ?h^-— -r -t o no -t -t t^ r^ a- -t lOPI CI m N M m N (ON cT -t \0 •"■ On -t ""5 O 00 ION On 01 O On OO O O00 lOO t^oo O gOD (N O Nm O -)■ -tNO -t O ID m « H 1- — M CO M ro Cl" O0\O m OOO S« N rOO "■ > t^ ton « ci lOO 10 -t 10 co Ci CI l>» m ci C£ O oo\ooo mo m c ) nO_ X i>> 10 of r<0 ci ~ m ci io coO I~> ?H cor covO CI ■-■ c~ 00 <0 if O ) CI xt- 01 — -t — -• ci -i-oo IO O CO 1^ C| 1 , ; r NO vO « rOiOK CO O tJ-00 O O O if ) HI On 00 .^OO ION SMNr>«00PI\O NO Pi 1-1 00 OO r» r-«. r>. O w 3 NO CI IN — >-. — CI CO vq O 4> C (J • • ■ a> m ■ ~ ^S a. in _ u «, • ^ '5 E uu. i : u. Culti mul tea frnil Raisin Sericu Stock Fish b Fisher — (1 P , H CHAPTER VIII SOCIAL EFFECTS The national life of the Japanese people during the past fifty years may be divided into two periods, with the Sino- Japanese War as the dividing point. In the first period, that is, from the Restoration of 1868 up to the Sino- Japanese War, we accomplished, in addition to the Restoration which re- placed the Shogunate with the Imperial rule, the introduction of a modern system of administration in place of the old feudal methods, experienced the Korean trouble, over which the leaders of the country differed, with a serious reflection on home politics as a result; and then went through the Saigo Rebellion of 1877. Through these events Japan accomplished great political reforms, her finances being so much affected thereby that the government was obliged to issue inconverti- ble bank notes to meet the needs of the time. In 1886, how- ever, the finances of the country were put right, and the value of paper money began to assume a close relation to that of gold for the first time after many years of financial chaos. On February 11, 1889, the Imperial Constitution was pro- mulgated, and the Imperial Diet was opened in the following year. The country was then just prepared to enter upon a period of activity, both politically and economically, with the one great aim of promoting the welfare of the nation, when the Sino- Japanese War broke out. Prior to this time, the Japanese had never had any experi- ence with international warfare, in the true sense of the word. They had had, it is true, frequent troubles with Korea and Formosa before this, but these troubles could not be called international war in the real sense of those words. In the eyes of the Japanese of that time, therefore, it was a great matter to be at war with China, the oldest and greatest coun- try in the Far East, with a history running back 4,000 years into the past. Indeed, the Japanese were somewhat appre- 278 SOCIAL EFFECTS 279 hensive as to the outcome. Fortunately for them they won, and this victory gave them the chance to realize for the first time the superior ability which they had been developing since the time of the Restoration in 1868. "To manifest the glories of the country to the world," was now the banner under which both government and people were determined to carry out their post-bellum program, prepared for the purpose of extending victorious Japan's influence. In accordance with this program the Japanese effected drastic reforms in their military system, business methods, and machinery for the promotion of culture. Simultaneously the cost of living went up, and prices of commodities and labor rose correspondingly. Development in business methods resulted in the concentration of capital, and naturally disturbed the balance in the distribution of capital in consequence. The figures in the table below were based upon the results obtained by the commission appointed to investigate the currency system. They tabulated the wholesale prices of about 42 principal commodities in the Prices of Commodities in Japan from 1873 to [912 Year Index-numbers Year Index-numbers 1873 100.0 100 102 .O 101 O I02.0 I04 O 109 ,0 108.0 103 IOI O 103 O 106 O I IOO 107 1 09 1 1 5 . 2 1 1 9 . 2 122.2 117 «» 122.3 1893 126. 1 1874 1875 1876 1877 1878 1879 1880 1804" i8<)5 :l 1896 1897 135 8 143-5 154 9 174 1 182.7 182.5 195 2 [86 3 182. 1 195-a 200 .9 1898 1899 I'JOO 1881 1882 1883 1884 1 90 1 I'll' 1 1903 1904 1885 1886 1905 1906 221 6 230 3 248 8 241 3 220 1 1887 1888 "'"7 1908 1909 [910 1 889 1 890 1891 1892 235 6 2478 265 1 191 1 1912 » War time. 280 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR city of Tokyo, of about 16 different commodities in the city of Osaka and of about 31 principal articles of export (prices at place of export). 1 In addition, the results of similar investi- gations made by the Bank of Japan concerning the prices of about 40 of the principal commodities in the city of Tokyo were used. As these figures indicate, the history of the rise in the prices of commodities in modern Japan may be defi- nitely divided into two periods, with the Sino-Japanese War as the dividing point. Each period has its special features. As the figures in the foregoing table show, in the twenty- one years from 1873 to 1893, the prices of commodities in Japan rose 26.1 per cent, or approximately 1.3 per cent a year, but during the war with China and in the several years there- after, or from 1894 to I 9°3> prices of commodities went up 69.1 per cent, or 6.9 per cent a year, and in the nine years from 1904 to 1912, or during the Russo-Japanese War and several years thereafter, prices of commodities rose 69.9 per cent, or 7.8 per cent a year. In a word, the prices of com- modities in Japan were rising approximately 1 per cent every year up to 1896, but since then they have been rising 7.8 per cent on an average every year. These figures therefore denote quite a revolution in the life of the Japanese people. That the prices of commodities have been rapidly rising in Japan since 1893 has already been stated. What were the causes of this rapid rise? This is a question which has been continuously investigated by government officials and indi- vidual experts ever since, but no decisive conclusion has yet been reached. As I understand it, however, one cause was the disturbance of the balance between supply and demand, especially in the case of rice, resulting in a rise in the price. Another cause was a considerable increase in the volume of currency in circulation, and yet another was the increase in the taxes, particularly taxes on consumption. The questions of currency and the increase in taxes will be dealt with later, so we shall here consider only the price of rice. From time immemorial, Japan has been known as a land of rice. Cer- 1 All these investigations were made from 1872 to 1893. SOCIAL EFFECTS 28l tainly rice is the staple food of the country — the people in general live on rice. 1 How to keep the price of rice normal, or to adjust the changes in it, always constitutes the initial problem in the Japanese Government's policy as to prices of commodities, and even as to economic affairs in general. Now the price of rice has been constantly rising since 1893, so great an increase as 90 per cent being observable in the ten years from 1893 to 1903, as the figures in the table below show : Average Price of Rice throughout Japan, 1893-iw";, Year Trice (per koku) Percentage 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 Yen 7.08 8-34 8.21 9. 16 11. 81 13 11 9 84 1132 11.47 12.07 13-68 100. o 117. 8 115. 9 12') 4 166.8 185.2 139.0 159-9 l62 O I7O.4 193 - It is a well-known principle that a rise or fall in the price of a single commodity will produce corresponding changes in other commodities, in the same market. It is obvious, therefore, that a rise in the price of an impor- tant commodity will be accompanied by a similar rise in the prices of other commodities in one and the same market. Besides rice, tobacco, another stable commodity in Japan. also rose in price, after the government had established its monopoly in the manufacture of the article. This rise in the price of tobacco affected the prices of other commodities too. Now concerning the rise in the price of rice, it may be stated that the amount of the rice crop each year was partially re- sponsible for it, but the principal cause of the rise in the price 1 Of the whole population of Japan, aboul 70 per cenl live on rice, so far as I li.i\ e been able to ascertain. 282 ECONOMH EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR of rice was the increase in consumption of those living on rice due to the general improvement in the standard of living in Japan, and for this the increase in the income of middle and lower-class people in recent years has been largely responsible. Let us look at the ratio of prices of commodities and prices of labor in the two largest cities in Japan, namely, Tokyo and Osaka, during these years, as given in the table below 1 : Year Tokyo Prices 8 Wages Osaka Prices Wages d 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 100 101 107 119 133 139 145 159 148 145 148 IOO. o 109.2 118. 6 129. 1 140.2 145-8 147.8 167.2 169.7 170.6 170.2 1 00.0 106.0 in .9 126.7 144 3 159-3 156. 1 173-7 173-5 1730 181. 8 IOO o I II .9 1323 141. 7 161. 6 168.6 169.4 183.6 179 3 182.3 199.0 • Average prices of 31 different commodities. c Average prices of 14 different commodities. b Average prices of 26 different kinds of labor. d Average prices of 43 different kinds of labor. These figures speak eloquently of the growing increase in the income of middle and lower-class people in Japan, on the one hand, and on the other unmistakably demonstrate a steady rise in the price of labor in the same country. Both facts were together responsible for the rise in the prices of commodities during these years. Wherever the prices of commodities and labor rise so quickly, the condition of society must be far from tranquil. Now, from the Restoration of 1868 to 1893, — a most eventful period in Japan's history, including as it did civil wars and a financial crisis, — the prices of commodities did not rise greatly, but they rose steadily after the year 1893. This steady rise in the prices of commodities could not but reflect the uneasy current under the surface of society during those days. 1 Based upon the investigations made by the Finance Bureau in the Finance Department. SOCIAL EFFECTS 283 The intervention of the three Powers, France, Germany and Russia, after the Sino-Japanese War, which largely deprived Japan of the fruits of her victory, seriously warned the Jap- anese at large as to the probable future of their country, and they accordingly made up their minds to carry out a stu- pendous post-bellum program to elevate the position of their country among the Powers of the world. Yet the glorious victory with which the Japanese concluded the war, coupled with their expectation of an inflow of a large amount of capital from foreign countries, because of the large indemnity which China was compelled to pay to Japan as a result of the war, weakened to some extent the apprehension created by the intervention of the three Powers as to the future of their country. In the financial world, in addition to the govern- ment's post-bellum program, many "fake schemes" were started by individual business men for various kinds of enter- prises. In spite of their rotten foundations, these plans worked smoothly for a while, and this fact tempted many other adventurers to start similar bogus enterprises. Thus was initiated a tendency which became well-nigh universal in financial circles until the whole of the country was shocked by the great financial crisis in 1901. The unusual rise in the prices of commodities and labor in the years following the Sino-Japanese War, as the figures in the foregoing table show, was therefore nothing but a reflection of the insecure condition of society in those days, when the majority of people lived on false pretensions. Indeed, it may be stated that in those pleasure-seeking days the people lacked sincerity somewhat in their mode of life, and that under the surface of society was running an indeed dangerous current. For a few years after the Sino-Japatiese War. the Japanese people, like many others in similar circumstances, lived on vaingloriously on account of their martial victory; yet they recovered their senses again during the great financial crisis of 1 901, and were able to meet the Russo-Japanese War in 1904 in full preparedness. All the circumstances attending these events will be further examined in the following pages. 284 economic ii i i < is of the sino-japankse war Prices of Commodities An inevitable economic phenomenon of war is the sudden rise in the prices of commodities which takes place in bellig- erent countries after the outbreak of a war. The Sino- Japanese War was no exception to the rule, as the statistics on prices of commodities in Japan during and after the war indicate. But in Japan except for those commodities whose prices went up either because of interruption in the supply, due to the outbreak of the war, or on account of shortage of stock, chiefly munitions, prices did not rise during the war, but did go up considerably after the war was over. Thus during the war and approximately ten years following, the wholesale price of the principal articles of merchandise in the city of Tokyo rose about 50 per cent, as indicated in Table I at the end of this chapter. 1 As the statistics in Table I indicate, the degree of the rise varies with the three classes of commodities, namely, food- stuffs, raw materials and manufactures, but it is true of all three classes that prices rose after more than during the war. Among the reasons for this rise, we may place the increase in taxes, especially duties on consumption, post-bellum enter- prises carried out by both government and individuals, in- crease in the volume of currency in circulation resulting from the business boom, and finally the luxurious mode of living of the people at large. All these, which may be called bad effects of the war, were responsible for the considerable rise in the prices of commodities after the Sino- Japanese War. As already stated, a rise in the prices of commodities in these post-bellum years undoubtedly resulted from the war, so I shall now dwell in more detail upon the effects of the war upon prices of commodities in the two largest cities, Tokyo and Osaka. The first appreciable effect of the war was felt in commercial circles, when the government chartered many of the vessels belonging to the Nippon Yusen Kaisha and other merchant 1 Post, p. 303. SOCIAL EFFECTS 285 marine companies, in the latter part of June, 1893, f° r the transporting of troops and munitions. As this interruption in transportation both by land and water — for railways, too, were placed at the government's disposal for the same pur- pose — came just at the time when the bulk of produce had to be marketed, the supply was suddenly interrupted, and prices jumped up in consequence. Especially was such the case with munitions. In the early part of the same year, or at least before June, the rate of interest was high and the price of silver rather low. From these two causes, as well as some minor ones, the prices of commodities in general had been going up, and while it may not be correct to say that the rise in the prices of commodities of that year was entirely an effect of the war, we may safely say that the war was the principal cause. The interruption to transportation at the outbreak of the war without doubt brought about a shortage of foodstuffs, etc., in the market, and merchants in anticipation of such a shortage had bought up as much as possible, without con- sidering whether the merchandise would sell well or not. The articles whose prices thus rose were salted greens, pickled plums, barley, soy beans, etc. Lead, which could be bought for 6.50 yen or 6.60 yen per 100 kin before the war went up to 10.50 yen in September of the same year, because, being a contraband, its importation was stopped after the out break of hostilities. Coal, too (best brand of Karatsu and Ho- chiku), jumped up to 48 yen in September, as compared with 31 yen or so before the outbreak of the war. Provisions also rose 30 or 40 per cent, for they were imported at Neuchang and Korea for the troops. But chinaware, umbrellas, silk fabrics, etc., which are not daily necessaries of life, and also seaweed, trade in which was interrupted by the outbreak of the war, rather fell in price after the outbreak of hostilities. The articles which were not affected by the war to any serious degree were soy, bean paste, kerosene oil, and articles ex- ported to Europe and America. In May, 1895, the Sino-Japanese War was concluded. Owing to the intervention by the three Powers, Japan re- 286 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR stored to China the Liaotung peninsula, once occupied by her army. For a while the Japanese were discouraged by this intervention but they soon recovered, and prepared for fresh activities in business. Just at this time the Bank of Japan began lending out money rather generously in business circles, and the condition of the country's foreign trade became very encouraging. The rice crop for the same year was very good. Furthermore, a large amount of specie was brought to Japan from abroad through China's payment of her war indemnity and by the improved condition of foreign trade. Soldiers and sailors returned home in triumph and were given decorations and monetary gifts for their brave services at the front. These factors naturally had their effect upon business through- out the country, and prospects in general became far better. In addition, enthusiasm for speculative enterprises became almost universal among business men, and quotations on stocks and bonds went up considerably; the volume of con- vertible notes issued increased in consequence, as well as loans made by the associated banks in Tokyo, and the business done by the Tokyo Clearing House. For these phenomena the development of industry may have been partly responsi- ble, but the principal cause was the increase in the volume of currency in circulation. If the volume of currency increases, the prices of commodities will assuredly go up. In 1896, the condition of the market became depressed, due to the govern- ment's raising of the taxes, the bad condition of trade in raw silk, cotton and tea, as well as the poor rice crop. Thus during the first half of the year prices of commodities fell somewhat. But this did not last long, for the Bank of Japan, by using the indemnity from China and the increase in its specie reserve, issued more convertible notes, which brought about an increase in the amount of bank notes in circulation, and thus the prices of commodities went up again. In 1897 the amount of convertible notes issued continued to increase. To make the matter worse the price of rice rose, and the lower-class people suffered accordingly. In October of the same year the government adopted the gold standard SOCIAL EFFECTS - N 7 as the currency system of the country, but this change was by no means effective in bringing down the prices of commodities. In 1898 business in Japan suffered a great depression, owing to the bad rice crop and the tense condition of the money market then prevailing. Prices of commodities rose accord- ingly. In the following year prices continued rising, and even later were rather on the increase, on the whole, although not without some fluctuations from time to time. It was from 1902 or thereabouts that business in Japan was finally freed from all effects of the Sino-Japanese War. Thus the rise in the prices of commodities during those years was caused by the tense condition of the money market and the increase in the volume of currency. And when we see that the Sino- Japanese War and the post-bellum program of enterprises by the government and people were entirely responsible for the increase in the volume of currency, the rise in the prices of commodities, and later the tense condition of the money market, we can not but wonder how far-reaching was the effect of the war upon the Japanese economic world. The rise in the prices of commodities during and after the Sino-Japanese War was principally due to such general causes as increase in the volume of currency in circulation, the tense condition of the money market, and an increase in the purchasing power on the part of the general public, although interruption in the supply of merchandise during the war and the raising of taxes after the war may also be mentioned as secondary causes. In the following pages we shall first note the fluctuations in the prices of merchandise in general, and then examine the case of each class of merchandise. In Tables II-IV at the end of this chapter 1 the index num- bers of the annual average wholesale prices of merchandise in the cities of Tokyo 2 and Osaka, the largest commercial city in Japan 3 , are given for the period 1 893-1 903. A comparison of these three tables shows us that the flucl ua- tion in prices of the several commodities differs according to 1 Post, pp. 304-310. 2 Investigations of the Bureau of Finance and of the Bank of Japan. 3 Investigations of the Bureau of Finance. 288 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR the commodity, location, etc. For instance, the rate of increase in Osaka was greater than that in Tokyo; and in Tokyo, of the three kinds of merchandise, raw material rose most, and foodstuffs next, while manufactured articles rose least. However, generally speaking, the prices of these com- modities fluctuated about the same in most cases, according to the prevailing state of the financial and economic market. And when we realize that it was due to the Sino-Japanese War and its effects that the financial market of Japan in those years was constantly disturbed and could not remain stable, we must admit that the war was responsible for said fluctuations in the prices of commodities, especially for the considerable rise noted. Let us now study the relation between the index numbers for the prices of commodities as given in the above-mentioned Tables II-IV and the percentage of the volume of currency in circulation, as well as the amount of bank notes in circula- tion, as given in Table V at the end of this chapter. 1 As the foregoing statistics indicate, the prices of commod- ities rose during those years which saw the volume of cur- rency in circulation increased, or in the years following. Such being the case, the increase in the volume of currency in circulation in the years following the Sino-Japanese War was responsible, we may conclude, for the rise in the prices of com- modities during those years. But as it may be premature to draw such conclusions from investigations covering a period of only a little more than ten years, I will give below the results of my investigations as to prices of commodities and percentage of currency in circulation during the period from 1887 to 1911. These results of investigations covering twenty- five years simply confirm my former conclusion. Such being the case, it is not too much to say that the rise in the prices of com- modities in the several years following the Sino-Japanese War was caused by the increase in the amount of currency in circu- lation due to the post-bellum financial and economic program. 1 Post, p. 311. SOCIAL EFFECTS 289 Comparison of Prices of Commodities and Currency in Circulation, 1887-1911 1887. 1888. 1889. 1890. 1891. 1892. 1893- 1894. 1895- 1896. 1897- 1898. 1899. 1900. 1901 . 1902 . 1903- 1904. 1905 1906. 1907. 1908. 1909. 1910. 191 1 . Year Index number for prices of commodities 102. 1 107.9 in. 7 1x4.4 1 10 4« 1 14.6 118. 1 127.2 134 4 145 1 163. 1 171. 1 170.9 s 182.8 174 -5" 170.6 s 182.8 193 7 213.6 215-7 233 -o 226.0 s 214.6 s 220.7 232.1 Percentage of cur- rency in circulation (1 886 = 00) 100. 8 105. 2 in 103. 4 s 106. 2 109. 2 120. 1 124 8 142 151 3 166 4 143 8 s 169 6 160 2 s 154 5 a 164 5 166 8 196 214 3 239 .2 256 . 1 254 5' 257 .8 286 9 306 3 Decrease, as compared with previous year. After the Sino-Japanese War, the Japanese Government raised the taxes on consumption of sake, tobacco, soy, etc., in order to meet her financial needs following the war. Let us look at the changes in the rate of these taxes. (A) The tax imposed upon sake in general varies according to the brand, and is very complicated compared with similar impositions on other articles. We shall therefore here examine the rate for the consumption tax upon refined sake (seishu) only. The rate imposed upon this brand of sake was 4 yen per koku annually in 1893, the rate having been decided in accordance with Order No. 61, issued in 1882, but it was raised to 7 yen per koku in October, 1896, to 12 yen per koku in January, 1899, and to 15 yen in 1901. (B) The rate imposed upon soy was at first 1 yen per koku 29O ECONOMIC EFFECTS O] NIK SINO- JAPANESE WAR a year in accordance with Order No. 10, issued in May, 1885, bill it was doubled on March 1, 1899. (C) The imposition upon tobacco was a stamp duty of 20 per cent ad valorem from July 1, 1888, until the manufacture of tobacco was monopolized by the government on January 1, 1898. After the business was brought under government management, returns from the business were at first 84 per cent compared with the price for which the government bought the business from individual concerns. The rate became 100 per cent from July, 1898, to August, 1900, 130 per cent from August 22 of the same year, 150 per cent in 1901, and it was quoted between 140 and 180 per cent, according to grade of tobacco, in 1902. The net profit of the government from its tobacco monopoly, or rate of income as compared with the purchasing price of the business from individual concerns, was 77.9 per cent in the fiscal year 1897 (from January to March) ; 86.2 per cent in 1898; 94.0 per cent in 1899; 88.1 per cent in 1900; 158.8 per cent in 1901; 178.8 per cent in 1902; and 152.9 per cent in 1903. The raising of the tariff rate by the government should also be noted in connection with the rise in prices of commodities during these years. In 1897 the Japanese Government pro- mulgated its customs tariff law 1 , which took effect from January 1, 1899. According to this tariff law, the taxable articles in Class No. 1 were 497, divided into 16 groups. These articles- were subjected to the imposition of a tax from the minimum rate of 5 per cent up to the maximum rate of 40 per cent. By applying these rates of duty to the articles imported into Japan from abroad during the year 1895, we get an average rate of duty of 12.3 per cent. But as Japan has a conventional tariff contract (treaty) with England, France, Germany and Austria, this treaty too must be taken into consideration. Even in that case the average rate of duty was 10.52 per cent. Previous to the promulgation of the said tariff law, the average rate of customs duty in Japan was 3.57 per cent. The following statistics show the relation 1 Law Xo. 14. SOCIAL EFFECTS 29I between the amount of the government's income from cus- toms duties and the prices of the imported articles upon which duty was levied, for twenty years from [889. As the figures below indicate, the average rate of tariff duty in Japan was 3.89 per cent for the ten years previous to the promulgation of the said tariff law, that is, from 1889, but it increased to 11.37 P er cent for the ten years 1899-1908 which followed the promulgation of the said law. Revenue from Customs Di cies, [889 1908 Year Rel urns from import duty Value of imported article s, upon which adopt many features of Western style to meet the various so< :ial requirements of their improved mode of living. Thus, on the one hand, the style of living in Japan was greatly im- proved, but on the other, tin- cost of living was considerably increased. As stated in the foregoing section-, the prio labor and the incomes <>t" the people at large increased in pro- portion to the rise in the prices of commodities during these 298 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR years. It we look only at these facts, the living conditions seem to have been very encouraging, but when we consider that the cost of living includes not only the daily necessaries whose prices have just been quoted, but also house rent, bath charges, etc., we shall understand more perfectly what effect the war really had upon living conditions in Japan. Thus, in the present section, we propose to examine the relation between the increase in the incomes of the people and the ratio of house rent, bath charges, etc., — items of expense which constitute a part of the cost of living. Before the Sino-Japanese War, with a view to ascertaining the recent changes in the cost of living of the people, the Monetary Investigation Commission appointed by the Finance Department of the Japanese Government investi- gated the prices of such commodities as rice, bean paste {miso) t salt, soy, firewood, charcoal, cotton fabrics, house rent and bath charges in the city of Tokyo, made averages of these, and compared these averages with the prices of labor and commodities in the same city, as follows: Ratio of Cost of Living to Prices of Commodities and Labor, 1 873-1 893 Items 1873 1877 1882 1887 1892 1893 Cost of living: Rice Bean paste Salt Soy Firewood 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 hi 138 76 130 125 100 106 123 165 184 221 158 157 305 226 129 150 246 103 153 86 138 153 127 112 192 216 151 197 108 154 158 179 118 226 221 154 192 95 156 162 Charcoal Cotton fabrics House rent Bath charges 165 124 225 221 Average Prices of commodities 100 100 100 119 107 106 197 95 90 142 104 131 168 122 128 166 122 Prices of labor 129 From the figures in the foregoing table it will be seen that prices of labor rose steadily with the increased prices of com- modities, but they remained far below the increased cost of living. We shall now continue the investigation from the SOCIAL KFFECTS 299 year 1893 on. As we have no authentic figures for house rent and bath charges during these years, we shall first com- pare the prices of daily necessaries with the prices of labor, and then compare them with the rate of increase in taxes, which was especially remarkable after the war. The average pri< es of some of the daily necessaries in the city of Tokyo are shown in Table IX at the end of this chapter. 1 According to the figures in this table, the prices of labor always advanced faster than the index number for the prices of commodities. They also rose steadily year after year, except in 1903, when they fell slightly. Bath charges, too, rose gradually during these years, while house rent rose con- siderably in response to improvement in the means of trans- portation in the city of Tokyo. Such being the case, it may be stated that the style of living of the people did not improve commensurately with the rise in the price of labor and the incomes of the people. In addition we must note the changes in taxes, which in- creased the financial burdens of the people, and indirectly made improvement in style of living difficult. The increase in the burden of each taxpayer (such as government, pre- fectural, municipal, town and village taxes) was 50 per cent in 1898, and 100 per cent in 1900, and this increase certainly reduced the scale of living to a considerable extent. The particulars are given in the table below: Comparison of Wages, Cost of Living and Taxes, 1 893-1903 Year Prices 'it labor Prices of daily in ' essaries I ration 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 100 n 109.8 1 24 2 132-5 145 152.8 155-2 [68 8 1705 171 .0 171. 6 100. o 109 2 IIS ,, [29 1 [40 2 145 ' S U7 B 1 (.7 2 169 7 170.6 170.2 1 00.0 [01 2 IO5 2 1 1 I 'i 133-8 1 p t> [87 2 [99 5 21 1 7 226.2 218 6 1 Post, p. 316. 300 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR In short, after the Sino-Japanese War, while the price of labor rose, and the general income of the Japanese people increased to a considerable extent, the burden of taxes in- creased also, prices of commodities rose, and thus the general cost of living advanced. In addition, the people developed a tendency toward more luxurious living; therefore the style of living in Japan did not improve at all during these years. And it may also be stated that these obstacles to improve- ment in the condition of living during these years all arose from the Sino-Japanese War. See Table X at the end of this chapter. 1 Population The economic activity that followed the Sino-Japanese War brought about much prosperity in cities throughout the country, and as many kinds of industrial enterprises were started in these cities, there was naturally, in consequence, a general demand for labor in such places, especially in what are known as the industrial centers of the country. In such localities the price of labor and the income of the people in general were rather higher than in the agricultural districts. Large numbers of people, therefore, moved from the agri- cultural districts to these industrial centers. They included many ambitious young persons who, stimulated by the gen- eral awakening after the war, left these districts to seek their fortunes in cities. Thus the tendency was towards a con- centration of population in cities during these years, as indi- cated in the statistics given in Tables XI (i) and XI (2) at the end of this chapter. 2 As the figures in these tables indicate, the rate of increase in the total population of the towns and villages was rather small— smaller, except in 1898, than that in the whole popu- lation of the country, and far smaller than the rate of increase in the population of cities. Among towns and villages, the population in those towns whose population is above 10,000 showed a considerable increase. Let us now consider the number of towns and villages l Post, p. 317. 2 Post, pp. 318, 319. SOCIAL EFFECTS 30I whose population is less than 20,000 each (Class No. 1) ; then those cities whose population is above 20,000 but below 100,000 (Class No. 2) and finally those cities whose popula- tion is more than 100,000 each (Class No. 3) with the popu- lation of these cities, towns and villages, and then compare them with each other. The rate of increase in the population of the towns and villages of Class No. 1 is smaller than in the case of Classes Nos. 2 and 3, and far smaller than the rate of increase in the whole population of the country. The rate of increase in the population of cities in Class No. 2 was a little larger, and it was largest of all in the case of cities in Class No. 3, as the statistics below indicate: Towns and Villages Whose Population is Less Than 20,000 (Class No. i) Year Number of towns and villages Total population Percentage of number of towns and villages Percentage of population 1888 7L295 15,810 13,947 13,224 I2,35i 35,874,298 37,275,893 39,384,980 40,974,(121 42,430,105 100. 106.0 109.0 1 11 .0 118. 100. 1893 1898 104.4 1 10.6 1906 1908 118. 126.0 Cities Whose Poplxation is 20,000 and Moke but Less Than 100,000 (Class No. 2) Year 1888 1893 1898 1903 1908 Number of cities SO 61 7- 1 80 95 Population I ,'808,726 2,270,1 10 2,520,151 3.098,251 -775.540 Percentage of population 100 120 139 171 208 Cities Whose Population is 100,000 and More (Class No. 3) Year Number of cities Population Percentage of population 1888 1893 1898 1903 1908 6 6 8 9 10 2,422,455 2,514.973 3.497,910 4.4,564 5.536,835 100 104 144 185 229 302 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SI NO- JAPANESE WAR The percentage of the whole population of the country means the rate of increase in the whole population of Japan. Observing the above figures in this light, it may be stated that the rate of increase in the population of towns and vil- lages, especially in those of small population, was less than the rate of increase in the whole population of the country. This indicates that the people of these smaller towns and villages were moving to the cities. The migration of people to cities is a phenomenon which is unavoidable with the advance of society. And the Sino- Japanese War, which brought about a general awakening of the Japanese people, may be considered one of the principal factors which caused the concentration of people in cities in Japan. SOCIAL EFFECTS 303 c a a cd — , "o ■/ c -. Zd J3 "o in C _o cd to in 0) c V bd ed u > < t~- c 1 - — r 1 ~ x x 1/3 ~ V '■j a a c O Nf^Noo -t-t-ti — t- -t- m cn ro -r -1- m -t -r m > — W cd «j *— •_ = id c cd — •- u 3 z r 1 ~ ~ 1 ^ 'i 1 - — '-T- '- u - O M M »N O M t^ ~ Z C*Jn -t- m -t- -r c - - § tn its 3 CO — Z - X -+■ C3 c*3 0- 1/3 Z N -t — c - -: — —. >,' = -: — t • •- - = ~ c - in -t--i--t-LO-t--t--r 4-J C O 6 u ed ft Q u c ca c SJ XI 'o > e bo cd Ih O O I^^O IOO00 h c T.n 0\C ^f. c -t- c X -f- 1 ~ C C - tc to -t "". -t -t -t r. > cd n ^S 00 ro -I" "~j O 1 - X 3f G — IN r»3 O^ C ' ' ! _ C O O 00 00 00 00 00 00 v 304 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR o X w o < > < NnO fOl^rOC* O fO On tJ- •+ t^ W> t^-vO fs n£> ""5 **■ O 00 N ■* "+oo r^ri->-c \n<-i r~» On \0 nO C3nO vO fONO "OO "5 -+ r*5 O ^nC 00 lOO r>. Cni vO >i ro NnO P« \0 O 00 rO fS 00 cn iooo on on i- Tt-r^o "-• on vo f^« n t^oo mow coo _,_-ll-l!-C>-lfN I- HI IO00 fN >- -> \0 C3 On i- CMOONO CN mvO •+00 00 r^i-i now ONTj-t^M icio lO C5 ON0 O n£> f^\D O nC rO O "+IOONCOIOO OnO CN i-i « (ON «» NOM (ON h ooooooooooo U (J N "O — OJ 'S c t- c -a — -s o* « o g y c u u a C w rt tj ? u_2-"S op.hjsortwgs SOCIAL EFFECTS 305 t*J M I s -j- — r, -j- LT. c, S, r\ oooHoonm "■. "■. "■. ; 3 I M>- <-\ <-i c — — <-< -r- — — _ _ „ r, r, _ „ ,_ _ — x -r ic c oo -t t c \r. r. is f. 1/-. - Is. c J 1 — hoc n -t- w CO"". — .: 3 -t- <-i N ■* ^ CI »4-X O O O*00 lOOO ts. — CMC lO *t O'rJ-ts.— c — c~c — m-i- •sf f5 fs.00 ts. CT Is. — Is. ir; O n o o is. m \n tr> u-50 •- o^ O -t tOfO»C NO " O O <"5 OO M IO O TfX CJ *l rJ-X IC^-O IDOvCI ts.'nj-ci x 1 s er x w^nosniON o fs. 01 x -t-c is.is-rx w. — c- ~ ~ ~ r ; ~ z s_ z ooooooocc c c ooooccoccc; oooooccc::; 01 - £ C H * O fl >, — *J .•* U K y y / j j — 306 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR r ^ a tn /. < n >-. < w 03 < 4- ro O vO vO 1^-00 t^\D C« CT> "*00 00 O oo t-^oo re 10^0 t>. "+00 SN. c*5 fj m fOrON O (OSMOm tJ-OO m t^. too tsio O ^J- s x Ov **5 r ^ lO rOvO t^OO c o "■.-".; c c 1^ O "~i rOOO IN^'I - ~ "-. ir. T >- t-» f>.vo o **• t^x o» Q vO ""- ic «P1 — — p<~ — — — — - — — ION O I^X CO >-< •*■-}•? fl ?". 1^ I^X r^»lT5>-r s <"7 »" MO C500 li-> O vO — X "O "0 -t Cl ^v— IT! — rC c*50 O X — 00 C^ t^ — -+00 rr; 0>N*N(0« t>. CO*C O N00 CJ OlOO !OfON» 3>NO -t- 10 m on 10 •* to ■* 00 N fO o-oo^ovo ion • r^\o ►« CS rOX -1- X> 00 00 O 00 o OX O h N B\D M hOO o - O MO i^h N O\m00 C- O 3^000 ooooocooooooo — o c B '5) •_ — = v '- - 3 j5 C L C - — • ' "- _! - — : O O O 0.5J3.b5'S C ~ ■"•- - UU^!UHUU.K>KS5SS bo < 308 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR U NO r-» "*■ O rt-vO CO -t'-O vO >0 u"> co O- CO >OCO in ■rt- >-> O O O I^CO rf O CS fS 1^ O •-< conO « M NO i-i 10 r<>-iMH-.i-i(Nri>-'i-Hi-ii-ii-ci-i NO Onco CO »OCS Oi a 0» O" h >-i \r> co >0 N -to rd >ONO p-- O t^ "^ O piM^MMI-llll-ll-ll-lt-ll-ll-l 1/5 CO CO On CO ""> 11 tJ-i-h O i-i O CS ICNOOIflHH) H « tO««H O 00 lOOvO COCO ION O hvO h rt •— ••—•€««•— ii— ••—>■—••—■—■•—■•—••— ii—i O ■* t^ m On i-i tj-00 CO ■*<» On »T> CO -f- co On 00 On t^co >ONO>N IJ 00 "+M t^ -J- >-i NO CO i- i- NO r<:rO HMCVIMMCMCMI-II-II-II-IH lO (N| NO O CI ON CN| 00 ICOtO COCO co m on no rfo lOCMCtoo m ►* NMO !0 IOC© 00 CN) i-i i-i NO CN| CO ,-,H(\|>-ll-ll-ll->l-/"3 N NO lOMOO ION CN| cOn NN!<3rtO -^"OncO mm^mhCSMmmmi-i w Mm ONhOONNOOO «NN io « <*• r-» coco co io «* o »o •*• •* NmiOOOCOOOMOhnO i-i O CO On ON '3- •"*►-< NO O cO-^->-i -+ CN CI On On M NiOfONO i-i ON N m\0 O O " O00 (1 O m OM Nino ■ O ^cor-^ioco coco vo mvO ■+ •cO'd-ONOfN) t^vo NO >-> rx,Oi-i -i-iOni-iOOOOCO 0000000000000 0000000000000 0000000000000 rt oJS 3 «15 rt^ bC«J (U o^ SOCIAL EFFECTS 309 1 - '1 ~ «-. -t m 'i r. 7 — r r r 1 - O fj 1 - r -r — — 1*5 ~ 1 -» -r ~ ~ ""- lOto^rtNMa - 3 '1 — 3 r "". — u-. i - \r. — — jq t*3 "". r x 3 r x OO cii^X) c~rc<^;x!X 100 O r>. t^ n OMC^-O 7COO Z Z ". OOONiO nX (i;: it,- tf ; on t^u-j — o rc-rc-*— 10— ^ O O N sO O N f.K N f, ir. ? - C C C "". r^ic«-t— r^.ccc". c : - ; oooocc;:cc;cc; B S &g£ g ~ 1 z I ^ >- ''• u " ' r u -• - •-•.- — _ / — -i w - «•" ^4 / < -• 310 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR O-00 O "IvO N h IOm NN N« ___ i _ i -i(>ii_iH(/)i_i I _i I _ii-i O i/S^i-oo cs 1-00 cjoo O "-■ **■ t^M CO rf t1- >- CN \£> OCO 1^ i/> rO ____ H ,r>)i--cirO>-i>-'"-<>-i r^^N li^oi .-.00 rj- fN \C fOir;7 MHI-IHNI-lMl-inrOl-lt-ll-IM O **■ (N O >-" rO 'd-vO O >-i N ►■« O vo ^lOiON i- i-h I-^u^i- IO00 ro rO "+ ^- "5 «*> s C too »>. hh IOM _ ii _ i _i_m i _ I i-iMCI>-i>-i>-i>-' Tf- CM O *10 0^*0 •"■ CO°0 U0M v£> lOO rtiOM (J\M M M J> TfOO ONOO vOiCroc^O'-'M'OOPlO «_.-ih-«i-ii-iO •* O ^ O^ COCO CM iO iOmvC rf- ^J- CM tONM OVO lOO «\0 t^ CM C »0 >-< ■* M t^\£! lO ■tf- O m00 * f ; \0 sOO * CO00 ro rj- ooooooooooooo O O y c XfQ&inOi jt. c/j to Q fe O W U SOCIAL EFFECTS 311 Index numbers for Bank of Japan notes and oilier paper money in circulation " ' "". r 1 - t "". — -+- to -f ; 3 — — "1 ; to n — '1 n = a a c = = y u 1.£ O O- r > T -Z S- N tO\D 0^00 ^x ir./. z~ — rr . x 00 bo u > < z r x so nioio^o n c -t C IX t^CC MC -i-- O C *- ^* <**. "~t" *t C ir, ir, * £ £ u 'o tn p CJ °C Ph c C I s * C> t-- — 0> r^oo 00 10 O c r>. to W OC -i — J — t- r^ —j — +■ C C — CO Tj- 1/5*0 f^oc ~ C — '1 "". 312 IXONOMK l.l-H-.c Is OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR [fl ir. i^ n o A m -t ot H 0) r^ -f oi fl -too lO ON fl ■ — "t — V ~ f 3 N NIX ci O 00 n -±00 00 IOm a» O -h-On "+. mm IT A "i- -t ■+ A «(H m (<)ioiO •tO'O -t- ■ N -t -+ fl fl ir. -t -t fl n NO -1 < M C*5 O -t CI -t O t-> a 1/0 01 O N « m CON00 O * A O 01 • fl h O M O C On flir A -t oi flO N NC^O iOmOO • 00 O 0) • A A O NOO -to A M nO 00 NO A ifi-t + SM o • rON N • MO 1/ 1^ » M M M M M oi I -1 OI Z ? M O ^> N 01 O 01 O O - i A N w O 00 O O ^t N A N O O o ON IO On 00 00 fl "~ N O N m -fs Nh mCmiO o^O fl nOO O O -t O 0\0 AO a c aoo no a a*j-ao ~ ?io+>o oo -i-x a 1^ H 0| _, _, _| M 01 M ^^ OOOihNO 01 O A A N i-h i-i NO OnnO •<*• O 00 NO tJ- fl >-i 01 O r> o o\ MvO m NO On O ■tflMO N NlflNOOO O 10«m OOfl 00 *t O Q- NO n O NO l-l 01 1/000 AO A A A AO O On -t flO NO >0 01 On t> W (N I-I IH M M 01 " o C 01 00 Tf A t> >*■ «0 *0 0> ON t^NO On fl O 00 iD00 00 O N " O 01 o x -ttoiCM io no N -t M O M OlNONOt^flUOONOOl t^O N — 01 t^ no OnO n n a i-i iDNO'^-'O'^- >t-H-NX OiO-tiO t^m N O h — — — — — — 01 1-1 ON 00 l^N^mf n OflOlOND O iO^-mOM N ^OO fl iO 01 01 o X 3 c CD On 00 A O O O i/)m -t- O lO i-i ON00 00 fl i-i On lONO rt-00 ON ION lO "- 'S t> I/O I/O «f I/O -t 01 N I/O lO **- A w (N to Tj- 1C lO IO rj- M -t "*A M ir,o -1 E 00 01 <+0 On O "" o OA"0AO AAOlOlNOOOOOTt AO "+OlO 00 on 00 oo oo "■> n it- oi 00 O ANO A00 NO OnnO Cn»/0OOO>-' t^A OrJ-01 IT i I cd •t IT. IT) lO ^- (N n0 i/OnO Tt-A01 0)01AA"0^1-AAt1- rj-^l- r-~ -j-O - t^. -3- O i-i O 1/0 N On uo^mOOn ONAONOl'rJ-OOt^O rj-XT) t^-oiO 01 01 00 A "*■ *i- ON ON NO o 00 t)-\0 AnO ON«« +0 O 3>0 "-tO O ^00 fO ^ fO fO f5 H -t- A-t-^l-^-A AOlAOl-i-rtAA-4- ^"A t^^-l/ -1 >. o O On N00 n N A O 00 i-i A O O O "0nO AOOmO hO 00 O O M On 00 O i-i N on On On i-i hN^ + O OnOAi-iAO"0i-iO t^uo t^vO^l \ CJ O A « i-i O O 01 A0101U01O 1/0OO1i-iAO11/0O)A A0) lOAf lO -tX HMMlfl 00 OOnOOOn OnO00nOOOO«O oo^t" wflO c On 00 00 01 -tr^^M no OOflOOl « O C)h +« O m O t^-+ «OnO so ■ C 01 i-i 01 O O OOIi-hUO-^- +0 O m n hO N N 01O i-iOi-i « -t- c - ^t-o O A N lONOOt tj-O"0O00OOi-iO OA ii « o 01 On O 00 « Tj- O « On NO O "5« nOClOAOOi-'O O M — — O p \ O O i-i -* o o O OOOOlOl oiOOOi-iOflOln O" "CO c fl o o o o o o o ooooo ooooooooo oo ooo On 00 o o o o o ooooo ooooooooo oo ooo c s 5 5 o o c o ooooo ooooooooo oo ooo c , , ^^ • , z ■ a 8 • 8 8.5 « ■ ' J3 ' 1 .0 2Q °-§ <_. s ° 5 en « 3 '3 £ 3 U5 •a - u ■J c '-0 T. - - / u / I - E 1) .Sf a- 111 i" c »_ Z i-i =: fe C •* -A jl « > s 1 u c > 3 I- 1- -* rt » ^ Mi e !r n c n) *j -f V u c c . rt CO 3 c ir. -a t » >/-. X - w to N - i/-. c 3 "". X — "■. r*; _ r^ ^ i/-. — N C N NtflO '- ""- T '1 — 3 1/ : k jm^vfiNci k »-t ■ - Z X Z 1 ~ — ? ir. 1 - — ' - — - 1 - 1 - i/ - . ir. y; i ~ _ 'i Ohioc 1 - 1 - x 3 10c 3nc t*3 5 1 - Z A. '. ": — — ION 3 O ir. t A 3 N NIOO <~. ~ c ><~. — ~ — r ' » 1 - "■ - 100c 1 - m oc d 1/5 w C in — "". -r 1*3 3 - a —a —-'.-'.- : O j - ". 'r. - 'f. : - — - - c 1 - z : - j — 1 - ". a •■) C "".0 ""."". 3 1 - X -r O r - it — z h SNIOO^IOK 1 - *i "-. — — — — — — — O \0 00 Tj- O IO CO N ><"- •"'■ O X Z 1 » 1/". 1 ^ C X r^OC SO>NN C -i — l/JO -t">3 N O 1^ 3 r>. N f! 3 1/-. 1/-. -1 m O ir. C J to "~. CO O N O 1/5 CO CO C ""• ir - X IO 3 t*l - z z z - z c — O "-. Z Z Z r. Z Z m ONION 3 A \n t — "-. — "■. "1 1 - "1 -t- -t- -t C C '1 — " - "1 "". -f — ^iohooomco 3 3 3 to c ic -r - 7 cooe -r "■. 1 - "". r 1 - '1 "-. Os r<-.-A C "OOCO-i— C-T3C ~ r r rr tr , -*■ c TO ON CO w CO N 1 - O CO CO w cove O O -1- to r, r^- _ r^- _ r'-. » r^ |/-, ,/". 10 O O 00 X (^ O N ". - - Z N O I--TI- — z CON — """. 3 — — 3* CO ^■nO \5 - c c z -1 z — '/-. '1 3 '1 -r — — _ — — — — — — — — — — — — — -t C -1- O O O sO «0 N z 3 - : Z Z 3 Z X O 00003:3::::::: 3333333::: c r A. ::::::::33;::: 00333333333333 lllll 8 3 .ES £ '. - = - - 3. - —1 r r . 1 - -i< — 5 2 c - c i a a 1 1- > r / c c; = en V i — ( C ~ z u s_ /■ g •1 E z 1 - u M - / X 'C — • = -. ■ — r. ~ S t E — - - --• ^ a E > 3- ! - c - - . - - 3 — - - ■- ~ ~~ ■ Z — - .— ^ — / --^: - 3 'C - ~ L - ^ / PS — ,2 ■Jr / -- / - - ^ _; 314 ECONOMU I Ml« rS OF THE si no-JAPANESE WAR SfOWOvN t"» N Mh-i/0OcoO"0 nO«OnOcO • -f l/> »0 nO co PI "5 < \£) mICO O "+00 hiOOOOcoO OOOPI ■ f)ifl"t^O* " O PIOOOnO<00 O«000 '10 00 00 00 o « -t - X ■ ir ; oo IO O "I " PI PI h M M h f| M M N PI H M P| M M M M M M B M C| B H (O vC <-> 00 «o io »o b-piOON"*cOO OOnO^hinOOcOOcOOOOcO O OncOO>OPIcoO nCCn-^-NnObbOOPIOnOOn n io Oi O pi ■> O -t- lOX h. rf coX) OnO O -t O u^X co On iO O hi N h. bh pi bb P| p| B N H B M P| B _|HlP|l-lP|HIHIHIH.HIHlP| rf hi CO C O ""J N M M N M P| M H P| H MH N M NM P|HMMM.MC|MM^ o h< hi icoo O "0 o OX O00 O NO O O OONMOO O (OiOiON o co N lOX ic io >o PI NO O O X bb O O PI IOnO -3-pi n>opi pi OX O >0\0 hi pi h. O i+nO XCco^tO- H.00XCO "-t-vO N -t OnnO Pi O PI M H P| M M P| B t|B BBf|B f|HBBBHIHIBHHIBHBHHIHlCO On hi hi OnoO C On CO O PI C "* C O O PIPIcONPIiOiOOcO iOnO N On CO ID 00 C iOnO O PI co O OX PI O co lOX OOO N 0<0 N Nh O O +iOPI PI C 00 -)- N N N co PI nO OXOPIcONCvO"00Ncoco-t PI HI HI P| HI P| HI M N M _ (\) BB f\|BBP|.-IBBH.BBHIHIBBBBp| 00 "tOMO>00 m o IOPI O PI NtCO OOcOPlXiO COnO lOX O "5 On rt pi i/"> PI lO cOnO bbcOPIXbbcoO OOcOnONP|COnOnOco>OX N t}- u"5 bb pi on N CO "0 N N M COON X OnX tI-IOnOnO "tX if NnO n lO On hi O ITJPI "t vOOWN ONO O O CN OiIOm O (i O O O On NOVO IC "t"VO hi OOOnOCXb-O OONPINNOOOOION 00 COnO PI cooo 00 cOb-itjpicoOX OCiOnOnCiOnOiOiOnOIONcO nO On co rt C 00 00 hi "t C O PI h. N C OOcOcONOhiOOOnOO Os "*■ "*■ O O "tNO X OOcoco^d-iOBHOONiOPIN NPI +Nh NnO PI "J- "t PI PI NO PI Tt"t"tCO"tPICOCO"tPINOCO HHHMMHH _, HI H, H, H, B- H, BBBHBBWBHBHN ID O CO "0 O CO hi rfr lOX O PI N co O COOnO"+iOQOOOOOnO"* ON 00 \T> rj- O "OnO •* N NO nC O 00 O cooo O O co "OX PI "d-O PI "0 N C PI m P| NO PI PI O N^-H P| tOPI ^ N HBMMMNP|C| (ON tJ- 00^-»000»/3 ^O O N ONO OOnOP)"*cOtJ-00000 On O PI PI NO O * iOOOOOOOnOO O O IOPI00 COX O O "0 O N C h. O co C O h. 0"t"t"OHO CCOOhiOOnOhipiOco o o o o o o o oocoooo oooooooooooo On o o o o o o c oooocoo oooooooooooo c o c o o c c cooccoo oooooooooooo , '. • ^ i ; to ; o . : s 0.2 ■ 'in . . s "O "«* ■3-S isho mit var • £ n 00 ^-^ s c u H L c c c c Ifl Xi - 1 , j r 7 BC b c >airers of on (watau perhangers t makers, vvics. . . . emen (lob borers (hire ;querers, u a cklaycrs . nds for oil aacco cutt (0 c « c oj - ■J u c = - C rt O S.S. eri - J2— c3 O j: H w c5'Ll't3.hn!« u ^i.tl)O^.^E«n«n L x. — r rg y OS c - A ^ -i.--: — : H- PQEHL f s !hr- SOCIAL EFFECTS 315 t^oo 10 1* r^ l/- f C X pi — to -r r ~ 'i 00 t^vO tO CO00 O C* PI O to ~ : '1 fi i-> -r -t -+• tO ic Tj-00 "". r l tO ~ r i f -T — "". C if. 1 ^ IC w m to to O O O fve re 1 - x i - 1 - ; x to to ■* t^-ro i-c r r CO 30 M C r to to -r 1 1 lONNN -1- CO i - O t-. r- c ~ r r C4 « « *flMMMNHM pi — - '1 '■i '1 ~ O CJO NiOOOOiO'+O c 1/3 r o r i c r to Z tO ~ r-rxrece "+0C to "". "1 - pi O f,(N '■i tO I^vC CI to -I-O 1 ~ '■i x -1- "i -r 00 PI « 1-1 [ z z — C t^. H HH flN~--'l-- - - - N N M M O fOt>. vO m PI O CO 'i r C C O 1^00 to vO >0 tON N h OtVO h«\0 C 1/". "". C 1 - c — to O fOOO fj (O N ro n "". CO Z r c c 1 - lt. w X n _ _ M COO 00 IOC too t-^o^o X x t^ m r^ "* PI «/} Tj- i/)NO fO C CO c z Jim vO 00 i-N r iC O vO ►>X N to to O f. to *t r l C -1- CO -C £ H M H |I)HHHHNHH MHM«MM O 00 00 O O O ?N« O r- t - 1 >■ r- c to c \fl Km 1- C^ O Pi 1^ "". **■ c : -tci-t- 00 <*■ « w \D m moo » tO-t COO vO «0 fOvC c M M M M tOOO CO 1000 t>. pi i^'j-o O ONOOtO tO OT 1 » <0 i/~. C C r i "". 1 toro -1- — M M\0 J\ a N m - 10 -t to rt X C 3 "" J vO "" t^\£> h» 00 O O N to N lO O •* t^ -iiDOC~r-c r-^cc to -1- -1- "~. tO C ION - r^ to c "t«o»o z z to tO to r i to ON« OOO OOOIONO : r c a z •<-. c> ONI O ic^O 3^0 1- c cm-:--:: Z T Z t O C t^ c - O c _ O fl <0 - OOO 0000000c OOOOOO OOO c c c qococ; : : cccccccc : 5 z z c c ; c 2 c 8 bfl w ! i c u> — • • • ? - .- r . ■ (/) . c rt ers akt ers 00 inders, book grade of a c ag H1.1 arness make lintcrs g - e ^ onfection abinet m heelmak ands fo C 9 Sc C r . - •/ 5 S S- 2 * co in 7 ji - ; • - « c - . > 1 v- B a 5 - - < L u :> — h < a CC^ cq xr -_ s > 31 6 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR X cO O On CO (N| t- -t CM CM "tiOO CO O O CO CM ON «^ CM t^OO ii 00 - t-» CO O NN -)-m t^co O >C ON *+■ -f CM O t^co ic IC t^ O On IC cO On >C iC t^. CJO ICO r*» i- 1 CM -+ ic r-. O t*. rt-00 O O i'i'iO 1^00 CO lOO cO " CM On OCN|-3-CMOO\OOCMiOTt-CM ICO CO O ico o cOcoOnOnN cO »0 © COO ifi^O NWO C t~» CM o On CM i- r-» o t-» CM On onoo rt" CM 00 O O ■ >-" O o o O COO COO CMncO>iio-i-CM-d- t^oo CO O t^ On M!JiO cm t^. C>) On CO CN O O r-» CM ICO lOlOO -too 01 -f X^ "" ) COO O ^f CO COO r^OO«CNi-H«>-'TfTt-CN) -1- -1- o OO CM ICO ■* n 00 CO r^O CO On O O O IC ii ON 00 fOtOHVfl "t COO O Oco OnO O t^ m ^ iC On cOOcOO-d-ONON'+O'-'O — MC^coc , 1 M M lO ^-00 IC^J-O IC t^ ON CM O COO t^cOiCO COO On CO O co co t^ 00 On *"1-0O On O On (^ cOO CO « O 00 (N On O ONO0 OC*-00OOOOiCC i c « n m hi Hi n _ — HI f> HI M HI "*■ 00 t^ CO00 cO^J-cOcOONOCO 0000 t^C 3 C, o, ON 00 On t-» ON00 tJ-O Tl-t^t^C lO CM O O TJ "■ - 1 - ON m Onm OnOnOnC O OnO m O OnO On O , C HI H HI H H* H H H H cO oooooooooooooooo O o ON 00 ooooooocoooooooo 1 O O oooooooooooooooo 1 O •Si a ■ — ". — s -o p O _u 01 -a as s • _2 c3 ^_^ hfl Mo S c Cl^H c a - 5 c z : PC k. Ij ■J — - — < Ci J c u: ) 5 > R b > z I c : ■- c - 1 c i i '- - - CC — a £ 1 < a. c - SOCIAL EFFECTS 317 X «J O l_ u. •n o - S art 3 ( 1 ' 1 r x ' ' ""• ' - ' 1 ~ e inn tax apil Z — 1/". — "". X 1- r - COO Z Z — "-. -r s. ~ — '1 — L- - - : ° u. ■~ -. 10 C t^oc 1 - ". 1 - r coo ft CJvC TfOC IANO ""- r < 1*3 c ■/ — . '- - - w ": ao m Ok ci m x c 2 a N N n '1 <-i c*J "-, -t -f -f -t ^ t*j 10 "i" rt ""» ""- 1 - o* 00 vD — h h n\o*C 100 z r*» fONO C X* 00" rC C "". - - X - 1^ O rOO r>. PI -f -t" <*5 3 CJOC "1 t>» PI t^ n 00 -t Z 1 - — — — '1 '1 rr> rC -"■ -f "". C C Oh -t-r-t--r-r-i--*--r-f4-**- CJ centag total ;rease O r*3 i/~> iTiOO N rO •- uiso Z NNinOiNPOflHN c c h nmo h n "3 -t t« C e 0H ir.l-N OOP fOO « <-> 00 cj — r r i — x ~ n f. -i- -t- __ : i>^fccx n c ~ 1 - cd ft ri \r, — * x" iC rC rt & 0> r"i00~ O ."- -t- "-. t^ t :Nt: n \o "o ■— 'P "~. 3" ~ -r X ~ r "1-r^i- X C -f - " CO00~\O C >0 PI* 00* 00 PI 1^ 5 C r i — ---■■HpiNfi 00 mO IT, 1CNO PI —OOOO 1 and lage 00 N-t X IOh OOO N *>VC ' n n N N ip, ? C N n t C en L =: i^ -i z 0ONH 0>O N« oo_oo ip. -j -r -1- c - "-. r -r ~~= tCvO «f rf - ^N IOC 'P. 'P. 2 — 1 ~ t^ — i--c r x — c x 1 - - a C l-~ X '1 — - 1 - _• "-. t^. -f ££ - — - '1 '1 "-. "-. rr_ -f ~T f ^^ "-. - — r "" Z 1 ~ '1 z z -~ ' ~ > r - Z — "3 1^ ir. ^ ip. 5 t Z r i ip. ip. C 1; S -tc i,i,-tir.t; - f, _ rt 3 NOiN*fU - : 'i; cc n 1^ •/} - -r -r c_ f ; - 4 c ip n ". - : c*3 — 1 - 1 ~ 1 , 1 , z Z 'P tip.O vO L. s ro -r ip. j i-x r z — - 00 OP. ■ g Z 15 o n £9 -- w B = ' ty -5 j 4 * - - - - 31 8 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR o Oh X < c a a n o o rtN 'ta^o n Rj i— i c O m Oh •a c rt C .2 00 vo t^oo r-» lO tOO CN CO O 00 00 t^OO o c tON rtO< iOO ^1- O^ •s c3 vO vO vO t^N O^h i-i o NVO lOO CM O ■* "-" H •^-vO >-i W>vO O vO "0 o PL, t^ t^00 00 00 ^ i-i O00 ^O (ON o T)-Tti-i ■* O vO ini- vo r-» o^oo on cO cn On rt t)-t)-h lOO tOM On cOnO C^CMOO O N o VO 1^00 ON CO r-- On 0) •^-•^Ti-^t'ioiiovooo Ph 1 1 1 < J > cOrfiOO t^.30 CO00 ^?^^OM>0 o 0000X1000000 On On SOCIAL EFFECTS 319 ©I ■- d u u"3 -3 ■d §> y 3 3 * - •* x x n a J MM -, — — J Q a -. 11 , -j. v. a •- — O O " - ■■ 000c:--"': c <2 O^O PO U3 — C P*3 fj >Ctoa T O r-x O O cp exeo <*> cf h •*: -r- 1- r o-rr-ro-ru-. t^ -1 N PO CI fO USOC — -r r-r-rm 01 > C « C 5S O 3 - - - - PL, = O 100. 100.6 [03 [02 g I'M 1 106. 1 [16 .>, O nj "5 a - X O r~ X r~ w. rfl fl n-ooxxi-xo ro « -^ ?to *f O* COO WI-Oii-l M -1 c in : -" — - -re - •/-. c c m 1^ t^ x" x" x" ~ m 0' u — c 0/ . M u Ed 11 ~> z. - t O •- IN in "-. 9 3 r;:r:ooo c "3 c. £ n r» n « r- « ^nOHnnab - I--TC t-CC H *» -rx x ? in - d — ro ^"ce - -r-o^x W IT. ir C C 1 - X X PO 11 ■ M Si 8 - - > m m n u) ci O IflX ~" 3 t 000-0- c a a a £ c r t- c "~ c pi - -r r r>se x m m Oi'C : -1 ti- c 3 a - — 1- — -r — -r r - ■ •f -f -f -f "■. - 00 X ' CHAPTER IX CONCLUSION The Sino-Japanese War was begun on July 25, 1894, an d on April 17 of the next year a treaty of peace was concluded. We have discussed in the foregoing chapters the effects of the war, especially as to expenditure and economic phases in general. It is not necessary to add more. Yet, on reflection, we note two or three points which may be especially dwelt upon in generalizing upon the phenomena which have here been presented — in particular the age-long weakness of China as exposed by this war and the awakening of Japan which followed the conflict. Prior to the Sino-Japanese War, the various nations of the world had regarded China as a powerful nation and one not to be held in contempt. There was a general belief in her fighting strength, and because she had the Manchurian cav- alry on land and the Peiyang fleet at sea at the beginning of the war, they thought Japan would certainly' be defeated. But after the commencement of hostilities, China suffered one defeat after another, and the dignity of that great Empire of forty centuries was completely lost. The "sleeping lion" at last became the "lion that does not awaken." What a tragic state of affairs! Thereafter, the "lion that does not awaken," with her mild climate, rich natural resources, and dense population, became the center of attraction for the world. There followed, in quick succession, the acquisition of important concessions — Kiaochow Bay by Germany (March 6, 1898), Port Arthur and Dairen by Russia (March 27, 1898), Weihaiwei and Kow-loon extension by England (June 1 and 6, 1898, respectively), and Kwangchow by France (November 16, 1899). The acquisition of a concession by one nation became the excuse for another nation to demand one also, and the latter an excuse for more demands on the part of the first. The European Powers were not satisfied 3-0 CONCLUSION 321 with the men- establishment of a concession, but concluded treaties for the nonalienation of territory, thereby establish- ing so-called "spheres of influence." At last came the dec- laration by America, in 1899, of the principle of the "open door" and "equality of opportunity" in China. The prin- ciple of the balance of power in Europe brought about a new- situation in the Orient. This was a by-product of the Sino- Japanese War. Japan had to face this new situation, besides undertaking various post-bellum enterprises. The conse- quences of the Sino-Japanese War were indeed serious. Now Japan began to realize her national strength, and in view of the changed conditions in the Orient after the war, planned the development of the national forces by starting various ambitious undertakings quietly and with united efforts. As a result, (1) expenditures increased, and (2) consequently the taxes of the people increased, (3) the cur- rency was inflated, owing to the various government post- bellum undertakings and the initiation of private enterprises, and (4) the prices of commodities rose suddenly. These were the noteworthy features. We shall show below the changed percentages as calculated on the basis of the year 1887 — the next year after the resumption of converting notes into specie. By the following table, we may ascertain the various changes which took place from 1887 to 1903. With [894 1895 as the limit, we notice especially that there have been . xtraordinary changes in all the various items except popu- lation. Before the war, the fluctuation was generally very slight, but since the war there have been extraordinary fluctuations. This was the result of the people's changed conceptions of Japan's position in the Orient, which material- ized in the ambitious post-bellum enterprises heretofore described. We consider these changes as a sign of extraordi- nary development. Thus after the war the phenomena of social lite completely changed from ante-war times. Society assumed an entirely new aspect, as if completely revolutionized. In other word-. 322 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR Fiscal Statistics in Annual Percentages, 1887-1905 a Year Expenditure Tax revenue Currency in circulation 11 Average price of commod- ities Increase in population 6 1887.. 100. 100. 100.8 102. 1 100. 1888. . 102.6 97-7 105.2 107.9 101 .4 1889. . 100.3 107.6 in .0 in .7 102.5 1890. . 103.4 99.2 103.4 114. 4 1035 1891. . 105.2 97.2 106.2 no. 4 104 -3 1892. . 96.6 101 .4 109.2 114. 6 105.2 1893.. 106.5 105.7 120. 1 118. 1 105-9 1894° . . 98.3 107.6 124.8 127.2 107.0 i895 d • 107.4 112. 7 142.0 134-4 108.3 1896. . 212.5 II5-9 I5I-3 145 -1 109.3 1897 •• 281.5 143.7 166.4 163. 1 no. 6 1898. . 276.6 155- 1 143-8 171 .1 112. 1 1899. . 319-9 201 .6 169.6 170.9 112. 8 1900. . 368.5 213. 1 160.2 182.8 1 14.4 1901 . . 335-9 227.1 154-5 174-5 116. 3 1902 . . 364.0 246.7 I64-5 170.6 117. 9 1903 . . 3I4-I 243- 1 166.8 182.8 119. 7 1904° . 758.2 530.7 256.1 233-0 125.0 1905' . 736.8 581.8 3°6 -3 232.1 I3I-7 • The percentage of the expenditure means the total amount of expenditure (net amount) ; the percentage of revenue from taxes means the revenue from taxes and the revenue from the profits of the monopoly bureaus. The percentage of currency was based upon the standard at the end of 1886, the percentage of prices of commodities on the average wholesale prices of forty of the prin- cipal kinds of merchandise sold in Tokyo in January, 1877, and the percentage of population means the population as registered at the appointed places of registry. b At close of year. ° Beginning of Sino-Japanese War. d Ending of Sino-Japanese War. e Beginning of Russo-Japanese War. 1 Ending of Russo-Japanese War. the Sino-Japanese War marked a new period, in which the aggressive spirit of the nation so notably shown in the period of the Restoration of Meiji had taken on new life after twenty- five years of quiet, and was now to replenish the national forces at home and develop her credit abroad. Furthermore, the remarkable development of the nation within so short a period was largely due to the spirit of enterprise shown soon after the close of the war. So the effects of the war as presented in the foregoing chapters really embody the history of Japan's economic development after the Sino- Japanese War. What we regret is the fact that the policy of the Japanese Government was not more carefully considered, since it was on account of the extreme haste to meet the new situation that the currency was inflated, the burdens of taxation were CONCLUSION 323 extraordinarily increased, and the prices of goods went up; consequently, while the income of the people generally in- creased in due proportion, the government undertakings did not fully meet the need of improving the living condition- ol the people. Fortunately, however, the people generally showed a sincere devotion to the country and were not seri- ously indignant because their living conditions did not im- prove pari passu with the financial and economic develop- ment of the nation. Xo serious social or political problems arose at this time. This fact should be set forth in bold- faced type in discussing the economic effects of the war. In short, the economic development after the Sino-Japa- nese War was in general so extraordinary that the phenomena which attracted attention before the war were no longer noticeable. But under all this apparent prosperity there was running a dangerous undercurrent, viz., the aforementioned rise in the prices of commodities, the inflation of the currency, and the extraordinary increase in the government's revenues and expenditures as well as in taxes. Thus we must not for- get that the effects of the war upon the economic world had a dark as well as a bright side. The bright side shone as the people endeavored to utilize wisely the effects of the war in meeting the new situation. The dark side was inevitable from the passing condition of our economic world, the evils resulting from the period of inconvertible notes, which had just been tided over, having reasserted themselves as a by- product of the post-bellum upheaval of economics. That the war was the cause of all this cannot be denied. But the nature of our economic world and the economic policies pursued in Japan were, needless to reiterate, still more re- sponsible for such a state of things. The Sino-Japanese War was, indeed, a test of our national strength and resulted in the self-realization and awakening of the nation, thereby bringing in its train a notable economic development. But there have been many examples in history of the downfall ol mighty empires even while enjoying great prosperity, such as Alexander the Great, the Roman Empire, etc. Indeed, 324 ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE SINO-JAPANESE WAR war is not a true cause of national greatness, nor victory in war a sure means of bringing about such greatness. On the contrary, there must be an irresistible rise in nationalism to wage a victorious war, which will prove only the first step in the advancement toward an ideal goal. The Sino- Japanese War was no more, no less than that, and it is far from our desire to extol the material and moral effects of war. INDEX Administration: increase of expendi- tures for, 43, 102-3; general expendi- tures for (1893-1903), 144. Agriculture: prohibition of resale of Japanese products of, in Kankyodo, 16; progress in, 89; Bank of Agri- culture and Industry, 90, 04, 107, 175, 178 et seq., 193; expenditures to encourage, 139; experimental stations, 273; capital invested in (1896-1903), 277. Amoy, 188. Anshantan, captured by Japanese, 31. Antung, Chinese evacuation of, 26. Aomori, i< <>. Army: organization of, corps, 25-6; size of, 35; rehabilitation of, 89-90, <»4 et seq.; four year expansion schei (1895-1899), 97 et seq.; expenditures for (1893-1903), 99-100; extraordi- nary expansion expenditures for -1903), 101; use of Chinese in- demnity for expenditures for, 120. Asan, 19, 21-2. Bakeuchu, 13. Bank notes: 51; issued by Bank of Japan (1894-1896), 55, 166, 286; issued to meet extra expenditures, 56; increased circulation of, 154; redemp- tion of national, 162, [67, 191 2; antee reserve lssui s of, [66, [68 et seq., 200; issued by Hank of For- mosa, [86-7; issuance of nal ne,| 1 [893 1 -mm 1 , with in- e it decr< ase, 197-8. Bank of Japan: 72, 82, 152, 155. 161, [93; loans in government by, 51, 59 [., 73, 75. 83, [58, [99; v, penses met by note issue of 0< Sn 4: 1896), 55, 166, 286; redemption of loans of, 76; enlarged business of, 90, 156, 1 75; deposit of 1 hinese indem- nity funds in, [22; purchase <>t bonds by, 125; increased capitalization of , 176. Banks: Hypothec and Industrial, 83, 00, 94, 175, 17N et seq., J74; national banks, 1 hanged to ordinal on, [93; oi Agriculture and Industry, 90,94, i<>7, [20, 274; subsidies to, 90, 103, n>7, [20, 170, [82; bonds issued by, 156; regulations concerning issue of bank notes by, 161 ; reorganization of, 175 et seq., iv-3 _ 4; development of realty, 178 et seq.; deposits and loans of (1893-1903J, 195; capital, de- posits, profits and dividends of (1893-1903), 207. See also under in- dividual headings. Banks of Agriculture and Industry: subsidies to, 90, 107, [20, [79; estab- lishment of, 04, 175: business of, [78 el seq. (1897 [903), 204-5, 274; re- organization of, 193-4; loans by 202, 274. Bellenue, Freni h missionary, o. lien, Li Sai, Korean Progre-M\e leader, 12. Bokueiko, Korean Progressivi 14- Bokukeiju, revolt of, 10. Boxer Rebellion, 132. Budget: of revenue and expenditi 47 8, I [893 1 9] J; for army and navy, 57, - icpenditures after 1896, 90; for 1899, 131. Business tax, 90, 129. Chaimucheng, battle at, 27 Chang, Li Hung, 12-3, 15; peace repre- sentative of China, 33. Chemulpo: 15, 21, 23; opened to trade, 12-,^; Tre.ii y of , [3-4. ( hilili, IYo\ ince of, 3] 2, 57. (holla, Province of, revolutionary movements in, 1 7. Chung-( hong, Province of, revolution- movements in, 17. Chungking, opened to conm ( ities, town- and villages: increase in annual expenditures for (1893 1 $8; ratio "I" increase <>f expenditures for [904 ><\ er t8< icpansion of expenditures for, [42; population of, 1 . ' 1 B93 [903 ,318 9; increase in population [905)1 in annual percentages, 322. ( !( >.tl, rise in pi i inial Bank of I lokkaido: busi of, 175 6, 17 s /at ion of, I9374. Communications Office, expenditures for (1894-190; \6. Conservative party, in Korea, 12 - 325 326 INDEX Currency: expended for war expenses (1894-1896), 57; scarcity of, 81, 83; inflation of, 84- 5, 154, [96; reform of, system, 118, 161, i<>5, 232, 235; in- ed volume of, 288; in circulation, in annual percentages (1887-1905), 322. Customs, revenue from (1889-1908), 291. Disbursements, monthly (1894-1896), 59; for government and private rail- ways (1 893-1903), 266, 268. Education: improvements in system of, 84, 89, 94, 112; use of indemnity funds to promote, 132; expenditures for, 138-9, (1893-1903), 151. Enterprises: comparison of expendi- tures for post-bellum, with total an- nual expenditures (1894-1903), 91 et seq.; revenue for post-bellum, (1896- 1903). 9 2 ! revenue for (1895-1905), 150; expenditures for (1895-1905), 141, 150; development of, 226. Exchange, rates of, in London, Paris and Berlin (1886-1895), 163. Factories, number of, and capital in- vested in (1893-1903), 212-3. Factory hands: number of (1893-1903), 211 et seq., (1896-1903), 218; per- centage of, to total population (1896- 1903), 220; percentage of adult and minor, to total number of (1896- 1903), 221; comparison of number of adult male to female (1896-1903), 222. Fenghuangcheng, 25; Chinese evacua- tion of, 27. Foreign Office: expenditures for (1894- 1903), 36. (1894-1895), 43 T 4. Formosa: 6; Japanese expedition to, II ; ceded to Japan, 33, 224, 229; fighting in, 35; Bank of, 94, 175, 185 et seq., 1 M4, 206; expenses incurred in, 103, 109 et seq.; railways of, III, 261; loans for development of, 115-6; ex- penditures for (1895-1903), 146 et seq.: production of sugar in, 229; trade of, with Japan (1897-1903), 230; passengers, freight, income, etc. of railways of (1897-1903), 269. Fortresses, expenditures for construc- tion of, 98-9. Foundary, iron: establishment of, 89, 04, 96, 27;,; expenditures for con- struction oi, 103-4: use of indemnity funds for construction of, 120. France: occupation of Kwangchow by, 7, 34, 320; interference of, in Liaotung Peninsula, 33-4; tariff agreement with, 233, 290. Fukushima, 106. Fusan: 9-10, 22-3; opened to trade, 13. Germany: acquisition of Kiaochow Bay by, 7, 34, 320; invitation to, to occupy Korean territory 7 , 12; interference of, in Liaotung Peninsula, 33-4; mone- tary system of, 162; tariff agreement with, 290. Goko, revolt of, 10. Gold standard: adoption of, 83, 123, 159, 163 et seq., 225, 232-3, 286-7. Great Britain: occupation of Weihaiwei by. 7, 34, 320; invitation to, to oc- cupy Korean territory, 12; inter- ference of, in Liaotung Peninsula, 33-4; tariff agreement with, 233. Griffis, Dr. William Elliot, cited, 8. Hachioji, 105. Haicheng, 25, 27, 29, 31. Hanabusa, Yoshikata, Charge d'Af- faires at Seoul, II, 13. Hangchow, opened to commerce, 33, 232. Heung-Sun, Prince, 9-10; Korean Con- servative leader, 12-3. Hiroshima: 43; Imperial army head- quarters at, 22, 50; telephone exten- sion in, 264. Hokkaido: colonial development of, 90, 112; plan for railway construction in, 106, 258; bond issue for railway con- struction in, 114; Colonial Bank of, 175-6, 178 et seq., 194. Home Office: expenditures for (1894- 1903), 36, (1 894-1 898), 43-4. Hongkong, branch bank at, 188. Hooshan, Chinese defeat at, 26-7. Hori, Lieutenant, military instructor in Korea, 12. Huanglinchi, 30. Huayuankow, 27-8. Hypothec Bank: establishment of, 83, 90, 94, 175; business of, 178 et seq., (1897-1903), 203; reorganization of, 193-4; advances made by (1898- 1903), 274, (1897-1903), 276. Income tax: 131; returns from (1893- 1903), 295 et seq. Indemnity: Chinese, to Japan, 12, 20, 33, 82, 119, 224, 286; transfer of, 57- 8, 77-8, 1 16; use of, for army expendi- tures, 90, 120; revenue from, 96-7, 119-20. INDEX 327 Industry: capital investment in 11896- 1903), 209-10, 219, 240, 243; progress of, 2 11. Industrial Bank: i<>4; business of, 188- 9, 206. Inouye, Kaoru, vice-minister of Japa- nese mission to Fusan, 10. Inouye, Ryoka, Lieutenant Command- er, 10. Interest rates: in Osaka and Tokyo, 65; on loans by laws Numbers 8 and 25, 77; paid on bonds (1893-1903), 117. Isotake-no-.Mikoto, 8. Itom, Prince, 15. "Japanism", 157-8. Jingo, Empress, expedition of, to Korea, 8. Judicial Office, expenditures for (1894- 1903), 3 6 . (1895), 43. 45- Kai, Yuan Shi, Chinese Minister, 13-4, 16-7. Kaidaichi, 106. Kaiping, 27, 29. Kanghwa Island Affair, 10. Kankyodo, 16. Kiaochow, German occupation of, 7, .34. 3?o. Kin, Kin Gyoku, Korean Progressive leader, 14; assassination of, 16. Kinchow-ching, capture of, 28-9. Kiuliencheng, 25; Chinese evacuation of, 26-7. Kiun, Kim Ok, Korean Progressive leader, 12. Kizuki (Izumo Province), 8. Kobe: extension of telephone service in, 106; encouragement to navigation from, 108. Komatsu, Prince, General, Chief of Japanese General StalT, 32. Konwasai, bat tie at, 27. Korai, overthrow of kingdom of, 4. Korea: population and area of, 3: Chinese and Japanese attitude to- ward, 4 c/ \,(/.; 11 2; Japanese expe- dition to, S; trade with, o, 12, 154, 237; independence of, 10, 14, 21 ; dis- turbance in, 13 et seq., 35. Kure, 106. Kuroda, Kiyotaka, chief of Japa- Mission to Fusan, 10. Kwangchow Bay, leased to French, 7, 34. 320. Kyoto: 124; extension of telephone system in, 106, 264. Labor: prices of, in Tokyo and Osaka (1893-1903 1, 282, 292, 294; pi in Tokyo (1873 1910), 293, JI2 1; fluctuation of price of i 21)4: pricesof, and commodities com- pared with cost t ", 61 et seq.; n tions for war, 64 66 et seq.; "Third", 68 et seq.: details of first three, 69 et seq.; receipts from war, 72: extraordinary spe ial, 72 \\ "Fourth", 74; based on laws Num- bers 8 and 25, 75 et seq.; for railway and telephone improvem at, 90, 114; for expenditures for Sino-Japanese War I [894-1910 . 1 [3; for industrial enterprises, 114..' seq.; for Formo6an development ,11- 6; sterling, n6; by Hypothec Bank and Banks of Agri- culture and Industry, 181, 202; out- standing, of Hypothec Bank 1903 . [83; of Colonial Bank of Hok- kaido, 1 85; of banks [893 1 103 ,195. Loochoo, 6; as a Japani --ion, 10-1. Manchuria, fighting ii Merchandise, value of, sold (1898- 1903), 242. Merchant Marine: subsidies to, 263, [893 1903), 270 <( of, 2 - Min, Prin nation of, 14. Miyake, Dr. Yuiiro, cited, 157. Monopolies; leaf tol . [26; in- jed revenue from tobai co, 1 32, 137: workings of, 1 34 1 1 Motienling, isaki: 1.;, t<>: subsidy for harbor improvement ai lephone ex- tension in, 264. iya: 105; telephone extension in, 264. Naval Office: expenditure [903 ,36; ext raordinary expenditures for (1894 |l '"' • : " \.i\ igat ion, subsidies for, [03, loi Navy: rehabilitation and expansion of, •. 04 et seq.; seven yt sion -chei 328 INDEX expenditures for (1893-1903), 99- 1 « m 1 ; exl raordinarj expansion expend- itures for (1896-1903), 102; use of Chinese indemnity for, expansion funds, 120. Negotiable paper, handled (1893-1895), 225, 1 1893 i3),239. Ncuchang, 285; encouragement to nav- igation from, 108. Niuchwang, capture of, 30-1. Nodzu, Michitsura, Lieutenant-Gen- eral, Commander-in-chief of Fifth Army Division, 23. Notes, government: issued, 160-1; re- demption of, 189 et seq.; cleared (1893-1903), 241. Okuninushi-no-Mikoto, 8. "Open door" policy, 321. Opium War, 7. Osaka: 124; interest rates in, 65, 75; ex- tension of telephone service in, 106; subsidy for harbor construction at, 262 ; prices of commodities and wages in ( 1 893-1903), 282, 292, 294; whole- sale prices in (1 893-1 903), 310; prices of labor in (1 893-1 903), 314-5. Oshima, Major-General, Japanese of- ficer, 17. Otori, Japanese Minister at Seoul, 22. Ou, Hung Tiyong, Korean Progressive leader, 12. Oyama, General, Japanese commander- in-chief of Second Army Corps, 25. Panic: financial, 83, 174; of 1899 and 1901, 159, 283. Paper money in circulation (1893- 1899), 171. Payment plan of war bonds, 65, 67-8. Peking, 9, 15; proposed attack upon, 32. Pescadores, occupation of, 31-2; ceded to Japan, 33, 229. Phung Island, battle at, 19, 21-2, 49. Ping-yang, campaign of, 21 et seq. Population: of towns and villages, 300- 1. (1893-1903), 318-9; increase of (1887-1905) in annual percentages, 322. Port Arthur: 25, 27; leased to Russia, 7, 34, 320; attack upon, 28-9. Prices: rise of, 81 et seq., 153, 158, 161, 273; of tobacco, 136; of commodities (1873-1912), 279-80, 284 et seq.; of labor and commodities in Tokyo and Osaka (1893-1910), 282, 292; com- parison of, of commodities with cur- rency in circulation (1887-191 1), 289, 311; of labor in Tokyo (1893-1903), 293-4, 312-3; fluctuation of, of labor and commodities (1893-1903J, 294; wholesale, in Tokyo (1893-1903), 303 et seq.; in Osaka, 310; of labor, in Osaka (1893-1903), 314-5; of neces- saries in Tokyo (1 893-1 903), 316; of commodities in annual percentages (1887-1905), 322. Progressive party, of Korea, 12, 14. Railways: construction and improve- ment of, 89, 94, 96, 103, (1893-1903), 145, 255-6, 258 et seq.; expenditures for new construction of, 105-6; con- struction of, in Formosa, 1 1 1 , 261 ; vol- ume of goods transported by (1893- 1903), 227; capital invested in (1896- 1 903) , 257 ; extension of private ( 1 893- 1903), 261 ; passenger, freight, income etc. of government (1893-1903), 265, of private (1893-1903), 267, of For- mosan (1897-1903), 269; revenue, disbursements and profits of govern- ment ( 1 893-1 903), 266, of private (1893-1903), 268. Receipts: monthly government (1S74- 1876), 59; from war loans, 63, 72, U3-4- Redemption: of war loans, 64, 66, 68, 75 et seq., 89, 113; Chinese indemnity used for, of war expenses, 121 ; of na- tional bank notes, 162, 167; of gov- ernment notes and bank notes, 189 et seq. Regulations for issue of war loans, 64 et seq. Revenue: budget of, for war purposes, 47-8, (1894-1896), 56, (1893-1903), 87-8; monthly, for war purposes, 52- 3; from occupied territory, 55; for ex- penditures for war, 58; for expendi- tures after 1896, 90; for post-bellum enterprises (1896-1903), 92; increase of, 94; ten year plan for (1 896-1 905), 95; from telegraph system, 131-2, 137; from tobacco monopoly, 132, 137; expansion of, of local communi- ties (1893-1903), 142; excess of, over expenditures (1 893-1903), 143; of government railways (1 893-1 903), 266; of private railways (1 893-1 903), 268; from customs duties, 291. Rewards, for war fund contributors, 43. Rice: area under cultivation (1893- 1903), 275; average price of (1893- 1903), 281. Rintsushin, 23. Russia: Port Arthur leased to, 7, 320; interference of, in Liaotung Penin- sula, 33-4. Ryuzan, 23. INDEX 329 Sake, tax on, 90, 126, 129, 289. Sanitation, expenditures for (1893- 1903), 151- Sasebo, 31. Scrip, war, issued, 55 et seq. Seoul: 10; Japanese legation at, 11; Treaty of, 15. Shanghai, steamship service from, 108. Shanhaikwan, capture of, 32. Shantung: 30; fighting in, 35. Shashih, opened to commerce, 33, 232. Shimonoseki: 10; Treaty of, 33, 35, 109, 118; telephone extension in, 264. Shiojiri, 105. Miipbuilding: subsidies for, 84, 89, 109, 254, 262; increase in, 210, (1893- 1903), 256. Sino-French War, 7. Sinonoi, 105. Soejima, Count, 9; Japanese envoy to Formosa, 1 1. Songhwan, battle of, 19, 22, 49. Soochow, opened to commerce, 33, 232. Soshojo, 22. ^o-himori, 8. Specie: prevention of diminution of, 56-7; effect of war on reserve, 155; decrease of reserve, 171. "Spheres of Influence", 321. Steamship lines: 107-8; subsidies to, 108-9, 20 3; statistics of, 270 el seq. Stock exchange, effect of currency re- form on, 165. Subsidies: for shipbuilding, 84, 89, 109, 254, 262; to banks, 103, 107, 120, ( 1 897-1 903), 179, 182; to Waka- matsu Harbor Construction Co., 104; to steamship companies, 108-9, 263. Sugar, imported from Formosa, 229. Sujin, Kmprror, expedition of, to Korea, 8. Susano-no-Mikoto, 8. Tai-Wonkun, 9. Takezoe, Shinichiro, Japanese Minister to Korea, 14. Takushan, 27. Taiko, Hideyoshi, expedition of, to Korea, 8. Tamushan, naval battle at, 24. Taohotsuon, battle at, 27. Tariff rates, 233-4, 2 9°- Tatungkow, capture of, 27. Taxes: in< rease of, 81 et sea., 90, 126 et seq., 280, 289 et srq.; readjustment of, <).s: income from, 127; to defray ex- penditures of Boxer Rebellion, 132- 3; business, 228; comparison of, with wages and cost of living ( 1 S<).>— 1903), 299; levied (1893-1903), 317; iue from, in annual percentages (1887-1905), 322. Teijosho, 13. Telegraph, revenue from, 131-2, 137. Telephone Bystem, extension of, 89, 94, 103, 106-7, 255. 264. Tienchwangtai, capture of, 30-1. Tientsin: 14; Treaty of, 5, 15, 17, steamship service from, 1 Tobacco: establishment of, monopoly, 90, 126; workings of, monopoly, 134 el seq.; revenue and profit from, 132, (1898-1903), 136-7; advances in man- ufacture of, 210; rise in price of, 2-1 ; tax on, 290. Togakuto Affair, 6. Tokyo: 11, 124; interest rates in. I extension of telephone service in, 106; prices of commodities and wages in (1893-1903), 2X2-3, 292; price of la- bor in (1873-1910), 293, ( 1 893-1 903), 294, 312-3; wholesale prices in (1893- 1903), 303 et seq.; prices of necessaries in (1893-1910), 316. Tong Haks, revolutionary movement of, 17-8. Torpedo boats: number used during war, 35; use of indemnity funds for constructing, 97. Toyama, 105. Trade: with Korea, 9, 12, 154. 2 pansion of foreign, 89, 1 58. 230 < / seq.; decrease of foreign, 168; foreign (1893-1895), 225, (1893-1903). 239. (1868-1903), 244 et seq.: between Japan and Formosa (1897-190; Transportation: progress in, 254 <•/ seq.; capital invested in (1896 i<><\ Treasury Office, expenditures for (1894-1903), 36, (1894-1897), 43, 45. Treaties: of Tientsin, 5. '5. 17: "' '876 (Korea), 10 et seq.; with western Towers. 12: of Chemulpo [882 . 1 .; - 4; of Seoul, 15; of Shimorioseki (1895', 33, 35; commercial, 254. Tsuboi, Rear Admiral, 21. Tsunp, Tai. Emperor, B. Tsuruga, 105, Ujina, 23, 32. United States: < binese treaty with, 12; monetary system in, [62;tarifl ment with, 233. Vladivostok, Bteamship line from, [08. rise in, s s: of factory workers compared with, of independent work- ers (1 899-1 903'. 225: of factory UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT LOS ANGELES UN: lY of CALIFORNIA AT LOS ANGELES 3 1158 00866 7353 ^^ UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIB AA 001 164 18 University of California SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY 305 De Neve Drive - Parking Lot 17 • Box951388 305 D L e ^ GELES CALIFORNIA 90095-1388 Return this materlaMoJheJ^^ APR 1 4 2008